LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATEPUE DATE DUE DATE DUE t‘t qun id LUUA C 33 \- ind 4 2 7 J‘Z-A 6/01 cJCiFIC/DateDuo.p65—p.15 PUBLIC DISCLOSURE OF CORPORATE ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE: IMPACT ON CONSUMER BEHAVIOR AND CORPORATE POLLUTION REDUCTION IN KOREA By J ongyeul Moon A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements For the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Resource Development and Urban Affairs Programs 2002 COP“ ABSTRACT PUBLIC DISCLOSURE OF CORPORATE ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE: IMPACT ON CONSUMER BEHAVIOR AND CORPORATE POLLUTION REDUCTION IN KOREA By J ongyeul Moon The purpose of this dissertation is to investigate the effectiveness of Public Information Disclosure (PID) as a pollution control tool. The main research question is, “Whether disclosure of corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) sufficiently affects consumer behavior to influence market share and consequently corporate interest in pollution reduction?” In order to predict consumers’ purchase behavior change, this study tested hypotheses about three dependent variables: 1) attitude toward corporation, 2) corporate credibility and 3) purchase intention toward products of the corresponding corporations. This study also performed tests about hypotheses concerning three moderator variables: 11) environmental attitude toward pollution, 2) familiarity with corporation, and 3) information credibility. Three hundred six Korean undergraduate students participated in the experiment designed as a two-group random assignment combined with pre and post-tests, between May and early J uneZOOl. Four currently existing Korean corporations and their four new unnamed products with positive and negative CEPI were presented as stimuli in the classroom setting of the post-test. “Within Subject Analysis” with Confidence Interval, Inference Probability, and Significance Test was employed as a major statistical tool. Data revealed that CEPI disclosure changes 1) consumers’ attitudes toward specific corporations, 2) perceptions of credibility of the corporation and 3) purchase 3?“- in: tr; intention toward products of the corresponding corporations in the positive direction for non-polluting corporations and in the negative directions for polluting corporations. This study also found 4) that positive correlation between consumer’s environmental attitude about pollution and effect of CEPI and 5) a strong positive correlation between information credibility and effect of CEPI exists. This study did not find a correlation between corporate familiarity and effect of CEPI. Based on these findings, this study predicts 1) that CEPI disclosure influences consumers to change their purchase behavior in the negative direction for polluting corporations and in the positive direction for non-polluting corporations, 2) CEPI disclosure can generate market pressures or incentives for corporations to reduce pollution voluntarily, 3) that PID can be an effective approach for pollution control, 4) that consumers’ environmental attitudes and CEPI credibility are critical elements that influence the degree of the effectiveness of PID, and 5) PID could be workable for even less known brands or corporations. Although most studies about effectiveness of PID have focused on financial market reaction to CEPI, this study focuses on product market reaction and consumers’ sensitivity to CEPI. This study provides empirical evidence supporting the assertion that PID can be a cost-effective pollution control tool, substituting for or complementing both traditional command-and-control approaches and market-based instruments, especially in developing countries. COPyright by JONGYEUL MOON 2002 {:8 P- '1 Of? (It Pro; COn‘ KICK] IEV;‘ ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to express my profound gratitude to my graduate committee members for their support, advice, insightful questions and intellectual contributions to this research: Dr. Eckhart Dersch - chair of the graduate committee, Dr. John H. Schweitzer - dissertation director, Dr. Ralph Levine and Dr. J 0 Ann Beckwith — committee members. Other than committee members, I would like to thank Dr. Kenneth Verburg, a professor emeritus in the Department of Resource Development and my previous academic advisor. Even after he was retired, he provided me with his intellectual insights and wisdom as well as editorial suggestions for my dissertation writing. I could not have completed my study without their enduring support and expertise. For their valuable contributions to the data collection, I thank my Korean friends: Dr. Jin-Won Lee in Department of Politics at Seoul City University in Korea, Dr. Yoon- Sik Jung in Department of Communication at Kangwon University in Korea, J ae-Bum Moon in Korea and Dr. Byung-Do Ahn in Korea. I extend my gratitude to my friend Dr. Euijin Ahn in the Department of Advertising at Youngnam University in Korea. He provided me with a great deal of insightful advice to strengthen methodological rigor of my research. Special thanks are extended to Dr. John H. Schweitzer and Urban Affairs program. Without their financial support and guidance, my study could not have been completed. I am also thankful to my family for their ongoing support: Youb Kim, Hoh Moon and Susan Moon. Especially, Youb Kim deserves special mention for her thorough review of my dissertation. Again, thank you all for your time and help! TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ............................................................................................................. ix LIST OF FIGURES ........................................................................................................... xi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................................... 1 Introduction to the Research .......................................................................................... 1 Statement of the Problem ............................................................................................... 7 Purpose of Research ..................................................................................................... 10 CHAPTER II LITERATURE REVIEW ................................................................................................. 12 Background of Environmental Policies ....................................................................... 12 Information Oriented Approach to Pollution Control .................................................. 20 Limitations and Advantages of Public Information Disclosure ................................... 34 Previous Cases of Public Information Disclosure for Pollution Control ..................... 43 Previous Empirical Studies .......................................................................................... 48 CHAPTER HI CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK OF PUBLIC INFORMATION DISCLOUSRE .......... 58 Assumption for Corporate Behavior ............................................................................ 58 Social Norms and Corporate Profit Maximizing Behavior .......................................... 59 Corporate Reputation and Environmental Information ............................................... 60 Role of Information: Stick and Carrot ......................................................................... 62 Conceptual Framework of Public Information Disclosure .......................................... 65 CHAPTER IV RESEARCH QUESTIONS AND HYPOTHESES ........................................................... 70 Research Questions ...................................................................................................... 70 Research Focus ............................................................................................................ 71 Research Hypothesis .................................................................................................... 71 CHAPTER V RESEARCH METHOD ..................................................................................................... 81 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 81 Experimental Design and Participants ......................................................................... 82 Corporations and Products Selected ............................................................................ 83 Stimuli .......................................................................................................................... 84 Measures of Dependent and Moderator Variables ....................................................... 85 Procedures .................................................................................................................... 88 vi CPI SI AP CHAPTER VI DATA ANALYSIS AND RESULTS ................................................................................ 92 Data and Subject Profile .............................................................................................. 92 Checking Unexpected Intervention between Pre and Post-tests .................................. 93 Stimuli Manipulation Check ........................................................................................ 93 Measurement Reliability and Validity ......................................................................... 95 Statistics for Data Analysis ........................................................................................ 112 Attitude toward Corporation ...................................................................................... 115 Credibility of Corporation .......................................................................................... 125 Purchase Intention toward Products ........................................................................... 135 Stimuli by Subject Interaction .................................................................................. 145 Environmental Attitude as a Moderator ..................................................................... 148 Corporate Familiarity as a Moderator ....................................................................... 155 Information Credibility as a Moderator ..................................................................... 163 CHAPTER VH DISCUSSION AND INTERPRETATION ..................................................................... 170 Summary of Test of Hypothesis One, Two and Three .............................................. 170 Summary of Test of Hypothesis Four, Five and Six .................................................. 182 CEPI Disclosure and Consumer Attitude Change (H 1) ............................................ 189 CEPI Disclosure and Consumer’s Perception of Corporate Credibility (H 2) .......... 194 CEPI Disclosure and Consumer Purchase Intention Change (H 3) ........................... 196 Environmental Attitude and Sensitivity to CEPI (H 4) ............................................. 196 Corporate Familiarity and Sensitivity to CEPI (H 5) ................................................. 198 CEPI Credibility and Effectiveness of CEPI Disclosure (H 6) .................................. 208 CEPI Disclosure and Consumer Purchase Behavior Change .................................... 210 Lessons from ModeratOr Study for PID Pelicy Design ....... ........ ................ 221 Influence of PID on Long Term Business Strategy ................................................... 228 Policy Applications of Study Findings: Implementation of PII) and Suggestions for Enhancing Effectiveness of PID ................................................................................ 229 CHAPTER VIII SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND LHVIITATIONS .................................................. 237 Summary .................................................................................................................... 237 Conclusion ................................................................................................................. 238 Limitation and Further Research ............................................................................... 240 APPENDICES ................................................................................................................. 243 APPENDIX A Questionnaires for Experimental Tests (English Version) ........................................ 244 APPENDIX B Experimental Stimuli: Type A and B (English Version) ........................................... 256 vii APPENDIX C ............................................................................................................ 264 Correlation among Familiarity, Environmental Attitude and Information Credibility Appendix D Inference Probability .................................................................................................. 265 APPENDIX E Korean Version of Questionnaires for Experimental Tests ....................................... 267 APPENDIX F Korean Version of Experimental Stimuli .................................................................. 278 BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................................................ 286 viii LIST OF TABLES Table 6.1. Stimuli Type and Mean, SD and SE of Stimuli ................................................ 94 Table 6.2. Factors and Number of Items ............................................................................ 96 Table 6.3. Inter-Correlation between Factors in the Pre-test ............................................. 98 Table 6.4. Inter-Correlation between Factors in the Post-test ........................................... 99 Table 6.5. Inter-Correlation between Factors in the Pre and Post-test ............................ 100 Table 6.6. Second-Order Factor Correlation in the Pre-test ............................................ 101 Table 6.7. Second-Order Factor Correlation in the Post-test ........................................... 101 Table 6.8. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Samsung in the Pre-test) .................................. 103 Table 6.9. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Hyundai in the Pre-test) ................................... 104 Table 6.10. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Nongsim in the Pre-test) ................................ 105 Table 6.11. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Binggrae in the Pre-test) ................................ 106 Table 6.12. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Samsung in the Post-test) ............................... 107 Table 6.13. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Hyundai in the Post-test) ............................... 108 Table 6.14. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Nongsim in the Post-test) ............................... 109 Table 6.15. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Binggrae in the Post-test) ............................... 110 Table 6.16. Measurement Reliability - Standardized or .................................................. 111 Table 6.17. Interpretation of Inference Probability ......................................................... 114 Table 6.18. Descriptive Statistics of Attitude toward Four Corporations ........................ 116 Table 6.19. Attitude Changes toward Four corporations ................................................. 117 Table 6.20. Descriptive Statistics of Credibility for Four Corporations .......................... 126 Table 6.21. Credibility Changes of Four Corporations .................................................... 127 Table 6.22. Descriptive Statistics of Purchase Intention ................................................. 136 Table 6.23. Purchase Intention Changes toward Four Products ...................................... 137 ix Table 6.24. Stimuli by Subject Interaction ...................................................................... 147 Table 6.25. Environmental Attitude toward Pollution and Effect Size of Three Variables ............................................................................... 149 Table 6.26. Familiarity with Corporation and Effect Size of Three Variables ................ 156 Table 6.27. Information Credibility and Effect Size of Three Variables ......................... 164 Table 7.1. Summary of Test of Hypothesis One, Two and Three ................................... 171 Table 7.2. Summary of Test of Hypothesis Four ............................................................ 183 Table 7.3. Summary of Test of Hypothesis Five ............................................................. 186 Table 7.4. Summary of Test of Hypothesis Six ............................................................... 188 Table 7.5. Attitude and Credibility toward Four Corporations before Stimuli ................ 207 Hi Fi LIST OF FIGURES Figure 3.1. Public Information Disclosure as Pollution Control Tool: Carrot and Stick Principle of Organizational Behavior Control ....................................................... 64 Figure 3.2. A Causation-Focused Model of Public Information Disclosure ..................... 67 Figure 3.3. Conceptual Framework of Public Information Disclosure .............................. 69 Figure 4.1 Hypothetical Diagram of the Effectiveness of CEPI on Consumer Purchase Behavior ................................................................................................................. 77 Figure 6.1. Attitude Change toward Samsung ................................................................. 118 Figure 6.2. Attitude Change toward Hyundai .................................................................. 120 Figure 6.3. Attitude Change toward Nongsim ................................................................. 122 Figure 6.4. Attitude Change toward Binggrae ................................................................. 124 Figure 6.5. Credibility Change for Samsung ................................................................... 128 Figure 6.6. Credibility Change for Hyundai .................................................................... 130 Figure 6.7. Credibility Change for Nongsim ................................................................... 132 Figure 6.8. Credibility Change for Binggrae ................................................................... 134 Figure 6.9. Purchase Intention Change toward Samsung Cellular Phone ....................... 138 Figure 6.10. Purchase Intention Change toward Hyundai Cellular Phone ...................... 140 Figure 6.11. Purchase Intention Change toward Nongsim Instant Noodle ...................... 142 Figure 6.12. Purchase intention Change toward Binggrae Instant Noodle ...................... 144 Figure 6.13. Inference Probability of H4 for Attitude toward Corporation ..................... 151 Figure 6.14. Inference Probability of H4 for Corporate Credibility ................................ 153 Figure 6.15. Inference Probability of H4 for Purchase Intention .................................... 155 Figure 6.16. Inference Probability of H5 for Attitude toward Corporation ..................... 158 Figure 6.17. Inference Probability of H5 for Corporate Credibility ................................ 161 Figure 6.18. Inference Probability of H5 for Purchase Intention .................................... 163 xi Figure 6.19. Inference Probability of H 6 for Attitude toward Corporation .................... 166 Figure 6.20. Inference Probability of H6 for Corporate Credibility ................................ 167 Figure 6.21. Inference Probability of H 6 for Purchase Intention ................................... 169 Figure 7.1. Attitude Change and Effect Direction .......................................................... 173 Figure 7.2. Stimuli Correlation of Attitude Change as Effect Size and Pattern .............. 174 Figure 7.3. Probability of Effect in the Direction Predicted (Inference Probability) ...... 175 Figure 7.4. Corporate Credibility Change and Effect Direction ..................................... 176 Figure 7.5. Stimuli Correlation of Credibility Change as Effect Size and Pattern .......... 177 Figure7.6. Probability of Effect in the Direction Predicted (Inference Probability) ....... 178 Figure 7.7. Purchase Intention Change and Effect Direction ......................................... 179 Figure 7.8. Stimuli Correlation of Purchase Intention Change as Effect Size and Pattern .......................................................................................... 180 Figure 7.9. Probability of Effect in the Direction Predicted (Inference Probability) ...... 181 Figure7.10. Summary of Inference Probability related to H 4 ........................................ 184 Figure 7.11. Summary of Inference Probability related to H 5 ....................................... 187 Figure 7.12. Summary of Inference Probability related to H 6 ....................................... 189 Figure 7.13. Attitude and Credibility for Four Corporations ........................................... 207 Figure 7.14. Moderator Variable ..................................................................................... 222 Figure 7.15. Mediator Variable ........................................................................................ 222 xii lntror confi Instr CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Introduction to the Research Pollution control policy based on traditional command-and-control and market- based approaches has not been completely successful. A new approach for achieving greater pollution control is emerging.1 It could be a powerful supplement or complement to the traditional command-and-control approach and market-based approach to pollution control policy. A group from the World Bank named NIPR (New Ideas in Pollution Regulation) introduced this idea as “Multiple Agents, Multiple Incentives: A New View of Regulation” (Afsah, Laplante & Wheeler, 1996, p. 7). The new idea is grounded on the principle that “one size no longer fits all for regulatory policy design: Optimal combinations of regulatory tools will depend on country-specific social, economic and institutional conditions” (Afsah, Laplante & Wheeler, 1996, p. 7). It is called the Information Oriented Approach or Public Information Disclosure (PID) for pollution control. This public information disclosure strategy was adopted for pollution control in Indonesia in 1995. Faced with growing industry and rapidly deteriorating environment, Indonesia’s National Pollution Control Agency (BAPEDAL) and the NIPR of the World Bank initiated the Program for Pollution Control, Evaluation and Rating (PROPER) for rating and publicly disclosing the environmental performance of Indonesian factories. PROPER assigned participating plants color-coded grades indicating their compliance ' Tietenberg (1998) stated that legal regulation is the first wave in pollution control policy, market-based instruments are the second wave, and the third wave is information strategies. He defined that information strategies involve public and/ or private attempts to increase the availability of information on pollution. with pollution regulations. “Gold” meant that the plant was a world-class performer, while “Black” signified regulatory violations causing serious damage to the environment and human health. Disclosure of this color-rated information functioned in the same way as credible threats of real punishment to the worst polluters (i.e., corporations with “B1ack”). Afsah, Laplante and Wheeler (1997) reported considerable improvements in compliance status both before and following the public announcement.2 The idea behind PROPER was to provide reliable and easily understood information about pollution to the public because reliable and well understood information about corporate environmental performance can create strong new reputational incentives for corporations to voluntarily abate their pollution (Wheeler, 1997) Our societies need a new approach for pollution control to supplement or complement the current pollution control tools because the current tools, the command- and-control (CAC) regulation and market-based instruments (MBI), were revealed to be very costly in some circumstances and incapable of achieving the defined goals in others. The pollution policy designers determine the ‘optimal pollution’ at the point where marginal social damage is equivalent to marginal abatement cost. CAC mandates factories not to pollute above the optimal pollution level. The pollution charge of MBI sets pollution price at the optimal pollution level and the tradable pollution permit of MBI allows factories to trade pollution permits within the limit of the optimal pollution. Both CAC and MB] have the following assumptions: 1) full information availability and 2) no transaction costs. However, transaction costs are not zero and full information is almost 2 As a PROPER—type programs, the Philippines launched EcoWatch in 1997, Mexico is developing PEPI (Public Environmental Performance Indicators), and Colombia also started a public disclosure program to complement its pollution charge system COI‘.‘ P0? £0) . 8d: ei’i never available in the real world (Afsah, Laplante & Wheeler, 1997). In other words, CAC and MBI can be effective pollution control instruments under the right conditions but it is unfeasible to achieve the right conditions in the pollution control practices. In this situation, it appears that the information-oriented approach could be a supplementary or complementary pollution control tool to both traditional CAC and MBI. The idea of information disclosure to control pollution is highly attractive to pollution control policy makers and designers, especially in developing countries where government enforcement resources are limited. Because of the ineffectiveness and the high cost of CAC (Tietenberg, 1985; 1990; 1995)3, MBI have been much more prevalent in the practice of pollution control in the United States (Tietenberg, 1998, October). However, in the developing countries the regulatory infrastructure for implementing MBI is insufficiently developed. In developing countries such as Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Indonesia, the monitoring problem is compounded by weak enforcement (O’Connor, 1994). Formal regulation in developing countries also has been greatly hindered by the absence of clear and legally binding regulations, limited institutional capacity, lack of appropriate equipment and trained personnel, and inadequate information on emissions (Hettige, Hug, Pargal & Wheeler, 1996). In the case of either traditional regulatory approaches or market-based approaches, developing countries are incapable of handling adequately the burden of designing, implementing, monitoring, and enforcing an effective pollution control system (Tietenburg, 1998). In this respect, PII) advocates argue that PID would be a new cost-effective pollution control strategies for the developing countries. 3 Tietenberg ( 1990) found that the CAC costs from twice to 22 times the least-cost alternative for given degrees of control. 3':qu 10:? em: Korea is a developing country similar to the Philippines, Colombia, Mexico4 and Indonesia which launched PID programs for pollution control. Korea has had some experience with information disclosure programs in the public policy area, even though they were not related to the topic of environmental protection. The Act of Disclosing Property Information of House of Representatives and High Ranking Government Officials was promulgated in 1993 in Korea. The Military Service Bureau disclosed the list of people who had evaded obligatory military service. Similarly, in the national parliamentary election held in 2000, tax information of candidates was disclosed by the Central Election Management Agency. Korean government released lists of those related to the crime of adolescent prostitution in public in 2001 and 2002. However, limited empirical data has actually been developed on the topic of the effectiveness of information disclosures. Hence, more research is needed to examine the effectiveness of disclosing corporate environmental information and its possible impact on pollution control policy in Korea. Even though PID was effective in Indonesia and applications of PID have been increasing recently in both OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) and developing countries, these facts do not assure the effectiveness of PID in different social contexts such as in the context of Korea. Korea is barely familiar with the concept of information disclosure strategies in pollution control. Measures to enforce disclosing information to the public, such as the Community Right to Know Act directing the release of Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) data to the public in the United States, or pollution control program such as Indonesia’s PROPER, have never been 4 The success of PROPER in Indonesia has inspired a similar program in the Philippines, EcoWatch and evoked serious interests in Colombia and Mexico. Refer to the website of NIPR at http://www.worldbank.org/nipr/. b I O ctr-mat In kcrce ”'5‘” 'n.‘.'..'_‘ .: rebut... .a’nL ut‘ U #43:} éEPAI .\f. ' ...‘ ‘ n 1 53.533325“ .\.;i. : an- iw 3 ' ' I;,":a" \‘L "‘00 n 'Ht 8:15 i ' .... ' x“: THC .30 ‘A C: C ' Damn-w . a ..... .‘1.I\ acm't't UH€,\.H‘:‘ I I ,I ten-0mm. -' Hr. ~.. “~59" 9n. ‘ ~¥HJgutcs :01' .N 53216 g ~0Ven'umcfl: a: We: - ' ‘ J: Intermauon ( ‘1. 12cm? conducted in Korea. Korea has not experienced a voluntary compliance and incentive program like the “33 /50” program initiated by the US. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). Most pollution control policies in Korea are based on the CAC. Even though a few MBI such as pollution charges or deposit refund systems have been employed, both the Korean government and polluters are unfamiliar with the idea of a MBI such as a tradable pollution permit. The power of capital markets and community action for pollution control in Korea is assumed to be considerably weaker than in the United States because the Korean community activists do not seem to have been organized sufficiently with the result that they have not developed enough power to provide a credible threat of adverse consequences for polluters in Korea. The various information disclosure programs hosted by the government and NGOs (N on-Govermnent Organizations) in the Korean political and social arena have rapidly increased. However, it is inferred from the lessons of the previous information disclosure programs that much strong and well-organized resistance from the comprehensive coalitions of Korean industry and the political majority will occur. Even though the environmental consciousness has continuously risen because of severe environmental conditions, top national priorities in Korea are still the issues of economic grth and national defense. Koreans might be lenient toward polluting behavior of industry because of the strong desires for economic growth. People’s desires for affluent consumption seem to be prevalent in Korea. Thus, even though PID is asserted to be a new cost-effective pollution control strategy for the developing countries, it is questionable whether corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) disclosure would be effective for pollution abatement in cu ‘ t‘,.. .‘Inv1=‘.‘\ “‘I' Ana 3 and...» CL- I ' ' 3 I1 '9‘.‘“ V .N“ v ‘ . Li .5)....‘ ‘AaL b a 5 DW‘W‘F‘I 9-0 -n-~ . bll\!lIA§&‘\L AAA\.. . 1.- . Ya.“ 81"“. 'i r -r IDS-tbs t- ‘ern‘Jn J. .. by»! ‘ . u...;. . AFRICA; h | o or?“ .- ~ I. .t‘atiion 0; Co" M ..Im€nl10l1€d b (is “ill . Chilge COnSU. .‘M Korea’s unique context.5 Hence, this study is designed to investigate the effectiveness of PID by testing the PID theory that disclosure of CEPI (Corporate Environmental Performance Information) generates market pressure or incentives for corporations to reduce pollution in Korea. A theoretical base of PID has not been well developed because PID is an emerging approach. Hence, more empirical studies are needed to understand the effect of existing public disclosure programs on the corporate environmental performance. Most of the empirical studies and theoretical assertions for PID focus on reactions of the stock market and the community to the release of information. Few researchers have made efforts to analyze the conceptual framework of PID. Little empirical research has focused on the reaction of consumer and product market to the disclosure of CEPI. As Cohen (1998) mentioned, before PID is more frequently implemented as a regulatory mechanism, we need to understand how the theory works and what effect PID has on corporate behavior. Thus, this study investigates the influences of CEPI disclosure on consumer purchasing behavior, product market share, and corporate pollution performance. It is based on the conceptual framework of PID, which suggests that CEPI will change consumer attitude and sense of credibility about corporations, and interest in purchasing products from polluting corporations. As a result, these changes in consumer behavior generate market pressure or incentives that will encourage voluntary corporate pollution abatement. 5 Even though Jeon (1998) asserted that disclosure of corporate violation had negative impact on the Korea stock market, this study does not rely much on his conclusion. For details, refer to Chapter II, pp. 54-55. I Statement of the PI Mr.) crap: til-3.5.x offor’p‘ ' 9.3.3201: (19‘15 l )1 1:233:35 tIRii In 1" mar trims cc; 4:" masons m 19:» ‘ A \'a¢~o m V. r O O I ’ .' . x .0 I.“ J . .. k\\ .‘ ‘t J “a . ' . . 33x. .t'JIC .1370?" n H Hui] , 5mm 115*" - Mimi: 5.3} ”If ‘ n" _ -u fittifmi’f‘l'fi ( ' [bx-3" .‘m' 9. w .116 teacher“. 0,2. ' was imposed b\ .2. . t.. Sitar-*1 ' ' t. I: In Bntzsht h t’n i *‘~ ~46 it‘ is " ~ 3601 men: ILLIO'A mg the I} “ OUI’IC Statement of the Problem Many empirical studies have focused on the stock market’s reaction to the disclosure of Corporate Environmental Performance Information (CEPI). For example, Hamilton (1995) studied the reaction of stockholders and journalists to the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) in the U. S. and found that statistically significant negative abnormal market returns occurred when TRI releases were first reported for publicly traded corporations in 1989. Laplante and Lanoie (1995) investigated the reaction of the financial market to the announcement of environmental incidents and lawsuits in Canada and found abnormal losses of stock value of Canadian-owned corporations ranging between 1.65% and 2% when the firms were found guilty (and fines are imposed) on the day the settlements of lawsuits were announced. Lanoie, Laplante and Roy (1997) observed the reaction of the capital market to the release of information such as penalties or fines imposed by the courts or regulators and announcements of lawsuits or suit settlements in British Colombia and provided evidence indicating that stock markets react to the release of information based on American and Canadian data. Konar and Cohen (1997) studied the reaction of the capital market to the disclosure of Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) and found that corporations with the largest negative stock price effects following the announcement of their TRI emissions were found, subsequently, to reduce their emissions more than other firms in their industry and also to make other significant attempts to improve their environmental performance by reducing the number and severity of oil and chemical spills. Dasgupta, Laplante and Mamingi (1998) studied the reaction of the capital market in Argentina, Chile, Mexico, and the Philippines to environmental news such as the violation of permits, spills, court actions, citizen nan-n""'" 'f‘ C ’ b‘.v-<.p--;‘c-§: lib :‘n ‘-I I . .:,,....v.,..1...,\ , hm. «\IJK’.‘ _... .. ‘ }‘\~ .3..."- Q ‘N. _' ‘- ok“) ...... ml K'IJKA c u I. v a .I F m - O .P........‘S. L0...;‘.;_fi . .' .L. ' .sxmc r. l. ‘4 i. u r , ’N'ivenm ‘ r . tl- .3r‘. .‘f bn'nk'i..a.§ ctd' : .I ' . . . .. a 1’1: gm ants abet: Watch: i 1w ““3” I “-Lhrlg‘i ~ 7‘ " ‘ «W. l. at. t complaints and protests, agreement between government and companies, investment in clean technologies and environmental protection, announcement of pollution abatement, government black list of polluters, and government actions such as warnings, fines, penalties, complaints, and company shutdowns. J eon (1998) examined the affect on the firrn’s value in the Korean stock market from both bad news about corporate environmental performance (e. g., the government publicizing environmental violations) and good news about corporate environmental performance that is released voluntarily by firms. 6 Wheeler (1999), Afsah, Laplante and Wheeler (1997), Wheeler (1997), Afsah and Vincent (1997), and Wheeler and Afsah (1996) provided empirical evidence suggesting that community influence increased as a result of the public announcement of environmental information. Improvement in compliance status both before the initial public announcement and following the public announcement, based on data from the PROPER program in Indonesia was noticed. The research about the effectiveness of disclosing corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) to the public for pollution control is currently taking place in Argentina, Chile, Mexico, and the Philippines7. However, we need to understand how the theory works and what effect PID has on corporate behavior before PID is used more extensively as a pollution control tool, as Cohen (1998) mentioned. “From an empirical perspective, the impact of existing public 6 For the findings of previous studies related to stock market reaction by CEPI disclosure, go to Chapter II, . 49-53. g”PROPER-type programs began in Philippines, Mexico, and Colombia. The results from those programs have not appeared yet (Wheeler, 1999). . I‘ n3".‘ k‘" r""- “'.. .»-' a r" '\ . 7“: 5“)“ . 93 scald 3" t " runes such as Kora if a stud) for; '31 in Korea is co::. fraction oithe prod .. COTSruction of the 1'." cartel. The outcom. I PI) works effectiu The result of this _~ the possibility that research “m prox': disclosure programs on the environmental performance of the plants largely remains to be tested” (Foulon, Lanoie & Laplante, 1999, p. 13). PID could be a very cost-effective pollution control tool, especially in developing countries where institutional capacity and resources for pollution control are limited. However, except the studies from the case of PROPER and J eon’s study, few studies of PID in developing countries were conducted. Little empirical work has been done on the product market changes and reaction of the consumers to the disclosure of CEPI. The idea of P11) is conceptually framed with two constructs: 1) CEPI creates public’s negative attitude and behavior toward polluting corporations, and 2) the public’s negative behavior causes corporate pollution reduction. However, few researchers formulated a theory of PID. Thus, it is necessary to conduct an empirical study focusing on the reaction of consumers and product market to the disclosure of CEPI in the context of developing countries such as Korea. If a study focusing on the reaction of products and consumers to the disclosure of CEPI in Korea is conducted, the study will become the first empirical study about the reaction of the product market to disclosure of CEPI and it will contribute to the construction of the theoretical base of the information oriented approach to pollution control. The outcome of this study provides evidence to confirm or reject the assertion that PID works effectively as a pollution control tool in developing and developed countries. The results of this study supply primary data and scientific evidence for predeterrnining the possibility that a PID program for pollution control in Korea could be effective. This research will provide basic data and evidence that strengthen the theoretical content and .. u a '9 1.00“” t. ~ I I. g..- .‘ob Va n-h bx 0‘” 1 .. u 1 e I ‘ ‘ ‘ t ' O _ .. .. ‘ 0 . I r... :L ’s.l‘-"\.s\.-5 .k . - I .‘| 1 O ' o ’, K \ . \ \ . é ”vs no an. .9- H- b ‘r M v.. - mmhéhgn anJ" .. I)" ’ 3 “¢- \\ .. ’Y'us. ' l W 9 . Kt .1") 3" A, M ’ r so“ «mist-Lu. “to ‘ Li“; ‘71 OiCEPld ‘R“ ~ xx ((1‘\ L4 \ causal structure of the idea of the infonnation-oriented approach for pollution control. The study gives present pollution policy makers and pollution program designers more detailed knowledge for designing a better infonnation-oriented policy and program. The results of this study are expected to facilitate the development of legislation for a “right- to-know act” and to initiate public information disclosure programs elsewhere in the world. The outcomes and data from this study can also be used in environmental studies and practices related to public involvement or community participation for environmental protection in areas such as environmental labeling, environmental advertising, green certification, green consumerisms, environmental justice, environmental journalism, the environmental movement, environmental education, and environmental attitude studies. Purpose of Research This study has three purposes. The most important purpose is to examine the effeCt of CEPI disclosure on the product market. That is, it is to investigate whether negative information disclosure of corporate environmental performance is likely to reduce consumer demand for products of polluting corporations, and consequently shrink the market shares of polluting corporations. The second purpose is to examine the conceptual framework and viability of public information disclosure (i.e., information-oriented approach) for pollution control. This purpose can be achieved by examining the causational relationship between CEPI disclosure and the changes of consumer’s attitude or behavior toward polluting or green corporations. The results of the test for the second purpose will serve as a direct answer for achieving the first purpose. 10 T' - I — 0'.»' "N .3€“"L‘: , wt 0 ”I .v \N',‘bl EA. .‘r‘ . , ... .. _l. M. -.- .:..... a .. .- 9'“) o I ._(.~.. I h.a§v [It {"7 .-,...J\. Ta” . - .-a-. 5'...\. L. ..5 u if " "‘9‘ R Us )Ho..aiah;. \. .. .... . t..- MS...” t. aq~.“. I! ., ,.. hp ~ 1 m I~o§ “.1. N45 tk‘:k\. . l 0 ‘fi. .. I ~¢ -),u .L‘Wv " Qt f“““‘dd C 21"". .255... The third purpose is to investigate the effectiveness of PID as a pollution control tool in Korea. Even though PID was effective in Indonesia, this fact does not assure the effectiveness of PID in different social, economic, political and environmental contexts such as Korea. Hence, it is necessary to examine the effectiveness of PID in a different social context. The third purpose also can be achieved from the results of the first tested purpose. In summary, the primary purposes of this study are l) to investigate the influence of CEPI disclosure on product market share and consumers’ response to CEPI, 2) to examine the conceptual framework of the idea of PID, and 3) to find supporting evidence for potential effectiveness of PID for pollution control, especially in Korea. 11 Ru; i .. litiground oi Em ir :V' VO‘O-m.g'.o ’ Ark ‘u...-...5..y . -~--»g1 up) ~ ‘v-" . -. . u'...__.._.\. *iu’K'. .... t H. NI}? 3 I‘ In. . ho .5-..‘ ‘\' . h c n am ”it.-. . ,5 1) ‘I‘ HP! u‘. - \‘1 ' ' ‘. ,_:§_ ||"“‘1:-‘ _. = "-4-?“ pariah”; . “M . ...\_ . ‘4. “it ‘ P " ‘ LA‘QI‘ h. thr\ g‘ hlfi‘m. vb, l‘ “\‘P‘h . - nud-K:.;l.\nz‘ of \}~ I M310“ tom 1 01 PC; 5 "‘14.. ., MAC“: (k. The ur‘ .- l AIL an, Ibrii are SUN. lies for T CHAPTER II LITERATURE REVIEW Background of Environmental Policies Environmental policy for pollution control can be classified into four categories: command-and-control approach, market-based instruments, voluntary incentive programs, and information-oriented approach. The command-and-control approach is a traditional legal remedy dictating environmental standards to industry, while market- based instruments is appealing to corporate profit-maximizing motivation using market principles. Voluntary incentive programs seek voluntary cooperative partnerships among regulatory authorities, environmental NGOs, and industry on the basis of social norms of industrial responsibility. The information-oriented approach seeks to impose embarrassment or shame on polluting corporations, undermining their reputations, and diminishing corporate sales and profits (Hoffman, 2000 a). Editiongl Environmental Policy: Command-and-Control ApproaLh Command-and-control (CAC) is a top-down legislative and administrative pollution control regulation. It sets the target for the total quantity of pollution emitted by all sources collectively and prescribes the best available technology that corporations should use for their pollution reduction. Thus, CAC is called “technology-based regulation” and the standards set for pollution control are called “technology-based standards.” The uniform emission standards as targets and a specific technology requirement are supported by effective pollution monitoring systems and by sufficiently harsh penalties for non-compliance. 12 1"...» '7'.” 9" 'N I ‘~ >84. ...... . -. w‘" T» . 1 ":2... i J ‘ ' nip " ‘1'."‘ '1' ‘ " ; I“ -5 in May _. - - CAC IS 8 13” '53", . ,t'n ’ '1‘ ‘ .qu‘x “db ‘L\tfi:“ V \AOU-q ~-~ I I “n” ‘r ~,)I v'a'fn‘ fl . :..t~a\¥.as5ss.s 5 '5 302716 35813 The meIcht" ,5 [is "tr" . .i\ 3'7“.“ H' ‘ A .-\5nsl\ail\ IOUFd ’v its: pollutants 1hr n l continuous hat 6 no his ' V A tnuronmcnt V Corporations f t0.“ 5 ‘ M eni'ironmcr" hr filament. Comor“ d. . C. AC does not prov; _ Q ~ Decause C .-\( The strength of CAC lies in its simplicity, clarity, and ability to command broad political support. The CAC system is easy to administer and very effective in the sense of achieving large reductions in emissions quickly (Beardsley, Davies, & Hersh, 1997). Thus, CAC has been the most widely used pollution control instrument in environmental pohcy. CAC is a less effective pollution control instrument than desired, however, because it has revealed problems that include a high enforcement cost and imperfect compliance (Tietenberg, 1985; 1990; 1995 ). For example, CAC has not perfectly achieved industry compliance with emission standards. The intensity and rate of corporate non-compliance with national air pollution standards is continuously increasing in some areas. The ineffectiveness of CAC is caused by its inflexibility and inefficiency, which is systemically found in CAC. CAC removes the incentive for polluters to discharge fewer pollutants than the regulatory standards require. Under certain circumstances, corporations have no incentive to devise new technologies to decrease the pollutant level below environmental standards. Corporations respond to incentives because corporate managers make decisions for their environmental performance by comparing costs and benefits for pollution abatement. Corporate behavior may change when the costs or benefits change. However, CAC does not provide any incentives for corporate behavior changes in terms of cost and benefit because CAC is not flexible. In the scheme of CAC, corporations have no freedom to choose the least expensive and the most effective technology, because the law 13 . 1x °H;‘ 'A F'- k .- - fi‘. . .~""' I ' ‘ ' r w I ' n \ of 3"» i ’ ‘ I W‘ .31- ”... ‘J I . iuu-";‘ - r... p l“ VI '0‘ .5. . ‘ \fi aLr .h" ' ~‘ . ~ I” s T‘s- "" .‘ H A” “1 ~ ~ 111“ . .u’n‘ ‘. " ‘. ....'.;i.-.I\. i‘i‘fl‘il I" ‘.‘lb‘.~i OL.’ L - -- "*---‘-u HA5\ A54“ 6 .‘tn'\ 1 -,4 I. r . Q...- " H ‘\ mirth) :OI' p..\.-u as; or pollution. so at a greater cost than 5‘ h... ‘ trio. 416 cost tunctir mtiCCilng infonnatio In sum. \\ he: iOCO ’r l ' no. pollution x decides the technology. The requirement for specific technology thwarts the use of less expensive and more innovative methods of achieving environmental goals. As a result, this inflexibility of CAC imposed high cost of pollution reduction on the corporations, and that causes the inefficiency of CAC. An empirical study conducted by Tietenberg (1990) found that the CAC costs from twice to 22 times the least-cost alternative for given degrees of control. The inefficiency of CAC is promoted by asymmetric information (Perman, Ma & McGilvray, 1996). While corporations may know their cost functions of pollution control, they have strong incentives not to disclose the functions of their marginal costs and benefits for pollution reduction to regulators, thus corporations may provide misleading information to regulators (Perrnan, Ma & McGilvray, 1996). As a result, the standards set by the pollution regulatory authority may not be the socially acceptable level of pollution, so corporations tend to attain the required level of pollution reduction at a greater cost than is necessary in the scheme of CAC. Thus, the inability to know the corporate cost function because of the insufficient information and the high cost of collecting information weaken the efficiency of CAC. In sum, where serious public and environmental health issues exist, the best way to control pollution would be dictating environmental standard to polluters, which is CAC. CAC is quick and effective to achieve low level of pollution abatement because the cost for a small amount of pollution reduction is small. However, CAC will be inefficient at the higher level of pollution reduction because as the pollution reduction is getting larger, the marginal cost of reduction is also sharply larger. The imposed technology choice and arbitrary target setting for emission, that characterizes the inflexibility of 14 u 0 F- . ' u g. I *3 “u ' "fig.“ ‘\ ' L‘s». 3.20 .5 - h .50. c . ,.T:_..o " c' . _A . ' . ‘ I .v .‘.I>~.L-‘.\ ‘ ' u. T. ' ,, . ' hatter. l .W l 47. 1‘." ‘ I Q Int .\;3. mat-cs t»; 12.-(0:2:ldfit‘i‘ or o: :1 1'0"?" e I e .A . .mzcl‘ndl 6.1:: CAC, also leads to the increase of pollution reduction cost. In conclusion, CAC does not work cost-effectively because of the high cost of pollution reduction caused by inflexibility and insufficient information. Market-based Instruments Most economists assert that the market-based instruments (MBI) can overcome the CAC limitations of inflexibility, inefficiency and ineffectiveness for pollution control. Tietenberg (1990) argued that MBI is a cost-saving tool for pollution control compared to CAC. MBI makes polluting corporations aware of the opportunity cost of environmental non-compliance or of pollution reduction, and leads to the internalization of environmental damage costs. Thus, it is asserted that MBI tends to result in pollution control being undertaken where the control is least costly in real terms. MBI includes practices such as pollution charges or pollution taxes, tradable pollution permits, deposit refund systems. I Pollution Cha_rgg Pollution charge (PC) has been used as a supplemental tool to CAC. Pollution charges are fees levied for exceeding standards (e. g., taxes on unleaded gasoline, heavy vehicles, etc.). Such taxes create incentives as every unit of pollution reduction is rewarded by a tax saving. Thus, PC achieves more efficient outcomes by internalizing pollution costs at the socially efficient pollution level through the modification of product prices. In the PC system, the pollution charge rate will affect the amount of abatement by working on price. The magnitude of the economically efficient charge rate should be equal to the magnitude of the marginal external damage of the pollution at the socially 15 II I ‘ L". 3‘ J D 2‘1. ..1.-‘L'-“' r .0...- ”. .p. 'u') r30 ' 6 bin. 51 *h‘ .u . -. - qr" ‘9 I “’1 ‘ 7““...5». II [S It..: .\ 5‘. o If‘.‘ a " .cfonor. 1995». l A: tw-epoildtzon ;‘ optimal level of pollution. However, it seems to be mostly infeasible to determine the efficient charge rate, because of uncertain abatement cost. If the abatement cost function is known, the control authority can determine what emission charge rate is needed to achieve any given level of abatement. If the abatement cost function is unknown, the amount of abatement that results from this charge will not be known. Therefore, in practice, it is infeasible to determine the economically efficient charge rate that can achieve the socially efficient optimal level of pollution and the quantity of pollution abatement achieved by the PC. Policy makers sometimes propose to raise the rate of pollution charge up to the level of a socially efficient pollution level because the costs for non-compliance is less costly than the cost for pollution reduction at high levels of pollution abatement (O’Connor, 1995). However, political feasibility is an essential constraint for setting an adequate pollution charge. The raised charge will be a burden on the economy and people’s economic activities, and as a result it will generate strong political resistance. Thus, it is not practical to raise the tax to achieve a socially optimal pollution level. _Tr_adable Pollution Permit. Tradable pollution permit (TPP) predetermines the level of “acceptable” effluent emissions or ambient concentrations, rather than acting directly on prices like PC. The pollution permits allocate this acceptable amount among polluters. TPP allows trading the pollution permits for money with others. Because the corporations have the responsibility to calculate the costs and benefits of pollution reduction, TPP induces corporations to develop least-cost strategies. In the TPP, the price of a pollution permit that is traded in the market is not fixed. The price is determined by the seller and the buyer so that regardless of the price of the 16 _ 9‘ ct .‘ aside Inertia») :‘ ..~-'-‘ 5111 3&4:ng s-m ‘" § -£..:SIIICIC‘T‘.C} and coral. The empznc P? is last cost?) ct Ho“ ever. I? maxed as t’oiio‘ A~ ‘ mnem c infonnu: inappropnateness of MicGiltra); 1990 hide system of TPE The diliiculf more flexible and C l mil-imam h‘F‘dimE adequate? : 1ng it. T. Q \ i‘iiii‘spoinn pollution permit, the target of pollution reduction will be theoretically achieved at the pollution level that is an acceptable effluent emission level pre-set by pollution control authorities. In the pollution charge system regulators decide the price of pollution as a pollution charge per unit of pollution, but in TPP, regulators decide the total amount of pollution (i.e. target for pollution control) and the market (i.e., buyers of pollution permits) decides the price of pollution because the price is changing to achieve the target for pollution control. As a result, it is asserted that the system of TPP generates more flexible incentives for pollution reduction than pollution charges. An advantage of TPP is its use as a cost-saving instrument. hr order to supplement the inefficiency and inflexibility of CAC, TPP was introduced in the area of pollution control. The empirical studies of air pollution conducted by Tietenberg (1990) found that TPP is least costly compared to CAC and PC. However, TPP also possesses several weaknesses. Disadvantages of TPP are summarized as follows: the absence of the market including extemality and public goods, asymmetric information, the moral problem of pollution permits, market failure, and inappropriateness of complete reliance on markets and market instruments (Perman, Ma, & McGilvray, 1996). In particular, the large transaction costs for information discovery in the system of TPP hinders trading (Batie & Ervin, 1997). The difficulty of designing and implementing TPP is another disadvantage. The more flexible and complex the instrument is, the more it costs in terms of designing and implementing it. Tietenberg (1998) stated that developing countries are incapable of handling adequately the burden of designing, implementing, monitoring, and enforcing an effective pollution control system. People, industry, and government in most 17 - ' 53" fl“ - ‘L “ db" '? ’ . q. " ra-fl " a a a . . u _- - . -.~nO-;'~.,'e v; ~us. bk‘.ls4a‘l5ss ‘3‘ A TEES. Some em: I New - ‘ ~ . c313) and sad 1 arseret‘im o! the developing countries have also little experience with the market for pollution control. Establishing a market culture and constructing the market system for trading the pollution permits in developing countries would take a long time and be very costly. Deposit-Refund Systems. Deposit-refund systems provide incentives for consumers to recycle or properly dispose potential pollutants or reusable resources (Batie & Ervin, 1997). Under these systems, consumers pay a deposit when they buy an item such as beer or bottled beverages and then receive a refund when they return the empty beer containers or bottles. Bottle-bill programs as deposit-refund systems are prevalent in the US. Some examples of deposit-refund systems include automobile tires, lead-acid batteries, and used motor oil. Buyers of pesticides pay an additional fee that is refimded on the return of the container to a designated disposal or recycling site. The deposit- refund systems in Japan require consumers to return household appliances including television sets, refrigerators, washing machines and air conditioners for recycling. Voluntary Incentive Program Voluntary incentive program (VIP) is a business-led environmental self- regulation, driven by existing or anticipated legislation and consumer demand (Batie, 1997). The 33/50 program is the first voluntary “Industrial Toxics Emissions Reduction Program” initiated by the US. EPA in 1991. Under this program, participating corporations agreed to reduce emissions of seventeen priority chemicals by 33 percent through mid-1992 and to achieve a further 50 percent reduction by 1995. The Green Lights Program was launched in January 1991 to encourage corporations to install energy-efficient lighting. The Common Sense Initiative (CSI) was started in 1994 as an 18 I ‘0- fl‘ "1 3-. ‘ ‘ ' buy—“w" .L \,. . . . . ’. :7." 'OP 'vn - ‘~-.‘;~‘~ s-wcb ”a-.. no" '3' V. ~ " . m'..-...r..a..uo '.x u. . :czsx'rzors to \t .. 3'"-'“.nw-,3v-‘ ‘ -' Nu -‘Cnh.-‘h;nsdd >i~1rN I .0".U I 0 r. m: to mgr. :: air ‘ ' Lane is to be a; A ‘1’).W‘. ,.....Incnt \ 0'. art 31°77? ~ ~ .56! tompdr‘ “ . “L5 REE its man‘s 0" ‘- \S tt-nnitment to the I ”aim and Safety, an J ”'t “1‘24 “MS and entirr II mnpetitit'e inceht" Penalties 21nd 1635 r“ media lS Par)E 1‘?! Van . nits lei els of 2 Th 5 tarr' é€i for p01} attempt to obtain industry participation in developing standards for the industry as a whole rather than continuing a pollutant-by—pollutant approach to protecting the environment (EPA, 1997). Project XL (Environmental Excellence and Leadership) was established to give exemplary individual corporations greater flexibility in achieving environmental goals. Project XL focuses on a facility and community, and it encouraged corporations to voluntarily design their own best ways for compliance with environmental standards (Batie, 1997; Hoffman, 2000 a). VIP specifies the quantity of pollution but not a certain technology as the method by which to reach the standard. It usually does not dictate how the environmental objective is to be achieved so that VIP generates the flexible incentives for corporations. A prominent voluntary incentive program is “Responsible Care,” which has numerous member companies that account for the basic chemical production in the US and Canada. Its member companies agreed voluntarily to the guiding principles that require a commitment to the public’s right to know, process safety, pollution prevention, employee health and safety, and product stewardship because voluntary compliances to pollution standards and environmentally safe practices for environmental protection provide competitive incentives for their businesses such as good image or reputation, less penalties and less regulatory sanctions, less attacks from environmental NGOs, and mass media. VIP is implemented on the basis of the cooperation and partnerships among various levels of government, environmental advocates, community and corporations. The target for pollution control is determined by government while the compliance 19 . «H . ‘fifi ‘ ‘ a u v. r ". - information Orie; The idea of msmrmental re my Understood ii ‘the. hi1 at .u " Cute COIZDI CENT“ .vnmental .\'GC lite" . nat'let stem to p 4 ME.“ ° ' «8~ then tradzr schedule and technology are determined by the negotiation among government, corporations, and community. A disadvantage of VIP is that it requires a capability for implementation. That is, high levels of institutional capacity and human resource are required to implement flexible systems in an effective and low cost manner (Batie & Ervin, 1997). Successful implementation depends upon clear performance objectives (e.g., standards), a clear negotiation process and the credibility of participants such as credibility of government agencies and environmental advocates because administrative discretionary power sometimes leaves to negativity among cooperating participants in negotiation processes (Batie & Ervin, 1997; Hoffman, 2000 a). Information Oriented Approach to Pollution Control The idea of an information disclosure approach to pollution control is simple. Environmental regulatory authority, such as governments, only provides reliable and easily understood information of corporate environmental performance to social actors who influence corporate environmental practices. Then, social actors such as environmental NGOs, the media, the court, community or grassroots organizations, and the market start to press corporations to adopt environmentally safe practices and to change their traditional business norms and strategies, which are based on profit maximizing and unlimited resource use. 20 5 "‘ UL" :7... .5 . I. C D -‘e ‘ ‘ __,). \J.l' t... ' ~ ‘3’" '- ~ EAA ‘ arOolfi. ; 35:11: order I -. pr v». ”'33? a Alt.“ 6),“ 9- Corporal: Drivers of Corporate Environmental Performance Governments and social organizations are two primary constituents that have historically driven corporate environmental performance. Governments have regulated corporate environmental practices through environmental laws. Social organizations, especially environmental non-govemmental organizations (N GOs) have mobilized diverse forms of social protests that can have a negative impact on a corporate reputation and performance. Environmental NGOs have used social sanctions such as protests and negative press in order to pressure corporations to adopt more environmentally friendly technology and to reduce pollution emission. Governments have done it by using legal sanctions such as civil, administrative, and criminal penalties. In terms of business management, environmental issues are structured as fundamentally external to corporate interests. Corporations do not need to initiate environmentally safe performances voluntarily unless the governments force them or environmental organizations damage their image or reputation. However, these legal and social sanctions gradually force corporations to change their dominant business norms (i.e., individualistic self-interested profit seeking and resource utilizing beliefs) and to transform environmentalism from something external to the market system into something that is central to the core objectives of corporate business (i.e., internalizing environmental costs) (Hoffinan, 2000 b). Hoffman (2000 a) breaks down these gOvemmental and social drivers into five categories influencing corporate behavior and managerial decisions related to environmental protection: regulatory, international, resource, market, and social drivers. 21 rum 9"). ‘. "x "ANNIE...“ L\). U 5' "F2. ’L’aa‘g ' ~‘\ «A .mnflu'l.) \UIT ~ I. -“ I n. «3103716313; 111.2 Mme-Know At Sissies of\\‘ild r, D it: 9 wit, the Ozone .\' . 10“71791118 of Ha; "Simmons; Regulatory Drivers. A regulatory driver is the governmental environmental actions that require corporations to adopt environmentally safe practices. These actions are authorized by law on the assumption that without regulatory enforcement, corporations would not voluntarily pursue environmental protection. Regulatory government actions evolved into several environmental policy formats in the US: 1) Command-and-control regulation that dictates the environmental standards on corporate performance; 2) Market-based instruments that appeal to corporate profit-maximizing motivation; 3) Voluntary incentive programs that seek cooperative partnership among government, corporations, and environmental organizations; 4) Criminal enforcement that threatens corporations by extreme penalties; and 5) Forcing disclosure of environmental information to the public such as the Emergency Planning and Community Right-to-Know Act in 1986 and the Toxic Release Inventory (Hoffman, 2000 a). International Drivers. International drivers are defined as international environmental agreements and international environmental standards related to products and international trade agreements (Hoffman, 2000 a). As the globalization of environmental issues has considerable implications for corporate management, the influence of international drivers on corporate environmental performance is increasing. International environmental concerns have primarily evolved into international environmental agreements such as the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (1973), the Montreal Protocol on Substances That Deplete the Ozone Layer (1987), the Basel Convention on the Control of Trans-boundary Movements of Hazardous Wastes and Their Disposal (1989), the International Tropical Agreement (1983), the International Code of Conduct on the Distribution and Use of 22 manure em :.'.‘=.”.' sec: or a set 0: x -. 3473;337:6111 and t :20 commie n2...- ecpxaton's 9:12;: restarts. Corp, -; :‘i‘. I , ‘ . 3‘ A -.t .0 00.1er lb!) .2'~l. k >4... Ls the Eur-op; Inertiatzon, !. 7'77“ ‘ Mandate. The t ‘ i CI ’5: . - _ m Eowming 1:: g . (hams-on Wilt Pesticides (1985), and the Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (1997). International environmental standards for products such as ISO 14000 have driven corporate environmental performance at the international level. ISO 14000 is a private code or a set of voluntary standards to provide a common approach to environmental management and eco-labeling of products and to integrate environmental responsibility into corporate management procedures. The ISO 14000 program addresses a corporation’s entire range of activities, from product design, planning or training, and operations. Corporations are required to adopt the international environmental standards and to obtain ISO certification in order to do business in certain multinational markets, such as the European Union (Batie, 1997). International trade agreements also influence corporate environmental performance. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is the oldest example of the governing institutions for most international trade. Others include the World Trade Organization (WTO) that replaced GATT, the European Union (EU) that has explicit power to enforce environmental regulations throughout the entire European Union, and the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) that was constructed to facilitate free trade between Mexico, Canada, and the United States. These agreements adopted environmental clauses that restricte corporate polluting behaviors to promote international environmental protection.1 Resource Drivers. Buyers, suppliers, shareholders, banks, insurance companies and investors are defined as resource drivers for corporate environmental practice ' There is a strong assertion that environmental protection is incompatible with tree trade in global free trade market (Soros, 1998; Mellor, 1993). According to this assertion, international trade agreements do not drive corporations to do environmentally safe performance. 23 ... en time tllor‘r’ Parasites for cont: Mes. contractors be one oitheir clients ‘ is sulipiier corpora: so: dam Were mor Steeter, 1999 ). Insurance 0| i‘liiCi gas egcaped Pestie ide Plant in E (Hoffman, 2000 a). Buyers control the consumption of products while suppliers control the acquisition of raw materials. Institutions or groups that control the acquisition of raw materials and the consumption of products can be highly influential in the way a corporation performs its operation. Shareholders, banks, insurance companies and investors started to apply environmental criteria to minimize risk in their investments. As environmentalism is translated into a core business concern of resource acquisition, processing, and sales, the influence of these resource drivers on corporate environmental performance is increasing (Hoffman, 2000 a). Some buyers and suppliers have developed their own environmental principles and started to require their contractors to meet the environmental principles. For example, Levi Strauss & Company has developed strict sourcing guidelines for selecting contractors that are different than the traditional guidelines about price, quality, and delivery time (Hoffman, 2000 b). It offered generous timetables, loans, and volume guarantees for contractors who met Levi Strauss & Company’s environmental principles. Most contractors believed that meeting these requirements and having Levi Strauss as one of their clients was helpful for their business (Katz, 1994). In 1998, Nike required all its supplier corporations to comply with US. air pollution standards even if the US. standards were more stringent than their domestic air pollution standards (Goodman & Streeter, 1999). Insurance companies equate corporate environmentally risky operations with increased cost of financial risk. Approximately forty-five tons of methyl isocyanate (MIC) gas escaped from two underground storage tanks at a Union Carbide Corporation pesticide plant in Bhopal India in 1989. Two thousand people died and another 300,000 24 ' - t _i) .... —,q q -_\ I'EE—QDKIA ts“ ‘. t :9» 1 9 .3 y... or «LI—Be 32‘ Lll‘ a. " mrszceratzon of 5 serious about the 1 Ll?“" _ I "45 Shcn as Sago. Cafldtla and 316 EU! had been injured by escaped MIC gas. “The scope of the accident and the exposure of Union Carbide’s insurance underwriters served to alter the structure of insurance liability coverage” (Hoffman, 2000 a, p. 74). UNI Storebrand, a large Norwegian insurance company, refused coverage to companies that failed to assume environmental responsibilities (Deutsch, 1998). In November 1995, the insurance industry developed a UNEP-supported Statement of Environmental Commitment with 78 official signatories to include the environment as one of the value-drivers in their under writing decisions (Hoffman, 2000 b). Banks are beginning to consider corporate environmental performance in their lending decisions to reduce the environmental liability risk. The environmental consideration of banks has been triggered by increasing court cases in which banks have been held liable for environmental performance of their borrowers. According to Hoffman (2000 a), the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill disaster which occurred in 1989 altered notions about the limits of corporate financial liability for environmental accidents. Some banks such as Salomon Inc., the Bank of America Corporations, the Royal Bank of Canada and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) developed a set of environmental operating principles and are beginning to examine the practices of the applicant and to consider poor environmental performance as a financial risk (Hoffman, 2000 a). Shareholders and investors are also beginning to make decisions for their financial investment based on the data or studies about corporate environmental performance since the late 19803 because they know that there is a positive correlation 25 ‘V ~»‘ 0" 'flfififl‘ .hvabvca 548‘ .o ~. .... .‘ I .‘ . qu'v I‘fi' .1 'F' N .’- -zbn.>~*¥ “.‘KU: . ... - 4;" it‘s .“ ' 5.-.}. Us‘;-\':“L' N w vwawafi‘" ' ‘ un'uLaha Base. 1‘ 5:8 .‘-ka ‘ h . 3}?.¢...\ tlrottrt. =kERESl “as 31.x) 1 (II N 3,. r: (4. r-1 1’ J ‘ prone a set of ter. 0. maestors. Accort esteemed that com vi ~ f» SHOP 4 ." :5 1m. III: ..o:.."nan. 1996. p will 19961. Ben if.“ 1:» . M the Sinsinaw. Star . es Bolts-m Gu OCCldemaI P€ll0i{-_ between environmental and economic performance.2 Shareholders and investors used their power through shareholder voting or by directing capital investment. For example, in June, 1988 the Social Investment Forum, a collection of socially oriented investment groups, developed criteria by which investors could assess the sufficiency of a corporate environmental practices in order to direct capital and resources toward those that behaved responsibly (Hoffman, 1996). The Council for Environmentally Responsible Economics (CERES) was also formed in 1989 as a coalition between socially responsible investors (SRIs) and representatives of several prominent environmental organizations in order to provide a set of ten guidelines for environmentally responsible behaviors to shareholders or investors. According to an early CERES mission statement, “SRIs advisers are concerned that environmentally unsound practices will undermine the economic health of corporations and therefore reduce the risk-adjusted return of investments in that firm” (Hoffman, 1996, p. 53). The CERES have solicited corporations to endorse the principles (Nash, 1996). Even without such outside pressures, shareholders have exerted environmental pressures on the companies in which they own stock. For example, in June 1999 the Sinsinawa Dominican Sisters (a religious order with operatives in the United States, Bolivia, Guatemala, and Trinidad) used their 100 shares of stock to force the Occidental Petroleum Corporation to reconsider its oil exploration program (Waldman, 2 “Research by Innovest identified a number of industries in which companies that rate higher on its scale of environmental performance produced better returns for stock holders than did less environmentally conscious competitors” (Deutsch, 1998, EU 7). [CF Kaiser International, Inc. found that companies with high scores on enviromnental criteria were considered as being less risky for investments and would thus enjoy a lower cost of capital and ultimately a higher stock price (Feldman, Soyka & Ameer, 1996 in Hoffman, 2000 a, p. 79). Cohen, Fenn and Nairnon (1995) found that good environmental performers also tend to be good financial performers. Dasgupta, Laplante and Mamingi (1998) claimed that a high level of pollution intensity may be a signal to investors the inefficiency of the firm’s production process. 26 .'.' . .. - Acct-ran to Rust 5 3a: :13: a cor?“ ., .131 sat-i is} where con. Mentsaid the) u ESDOHSC to a July 1 tempts} 's emimr: The dema" green products is ‘0' Irradiation. S)mhet. hctnones. Sales of bison) to 1994 (T; gailons) to 1995 t" meltNd from 195 1999). Thus, shareholders and investors appear as powerful forces for environmentally safe performance of corporations since the late 19805 (Hoffman, 2000 b). Market Drivers. Consumers include environmental concerns in their purchasing decisions. The environmental behavior of consumerism has been termed “green consumerism.” Green consumerism is an outcome of public awareness of environmental problems and of support for environmental protection. The advocates for green consumerism believe that products should be more environmentally accountable in use. According to Rosendahl’s (1990) findings from a 1989 survey, 77 percent of Americans said that a company’s environmental reputation affected what they bought, 89 percent said they were concerned about the environmental impact of products purchased, and 78 percent said they were willing to pay more for recyclable or biodegradable packaging. In response to a July 1989 survey, 77 percent of Americans answered that they consider a company’s environmental reputation when they made purchases (Krupp, 1990). The demand for green products is continuously growing. One example of such green products is organic foods that are free from artificial preservatives, coloring, irradiation, synthetic pesticides, fungicides, ripening agents, fumigants, and growth hormones. Sales of organic foods doubled in the five years period from 1989 ($ 3.9 billion) to 1994 (7.6 billion). Sales of bottled water tripled from 1984 (933 million gallons) to 1995 (2.87 billion gallons). Health-food supermarkets across the US. increased from 195 stores in 1991 to 650 stores in 1994 (Burros, 1996). Organizational expression of green consumerism is a boycott to reject the purchase of particular corporations’ products. For example, consumers boycotted Burger King in order to pressure the company to modify its purchase of imported beef from 27 {3:21. Amend. L . - . 9‘7.‘. 1... "'3\- 56%-”; .0 b5.\ . »_ ... Etta: receix ct. ox c ~~~4m "r beta. tor. Corporate 1:11»: ' '0... m :0: Dre-“KM... I ”id- Iht inc: Sort E3331] fem; kmlailm companies Care bOUrit P650171] an; chemlciil ii ”Cider“ at cmi”3mm Shalegles 11151 little in Texiiie M E environmental performance. Therefore, it appears that compliance of polluting corporations with social norms or community desires is also a profit-maximizing behavior. Corporate Reputation and Environmental Information Information about corporate environmental performance disclosed to the public for promoting pollution control would be very effective, especially in the situation where environmental reputation plays an important role in determining business strategies, consumers’ purchase behavior, and investors’ financial investment decisions. Damage to the image and reputation of polluting corporations becomes the pressure or motivation and the incentive for pollution reduction. Some corporations became concerned about their environmental reputations (i.e., green reputation) in their business strategies. For example, the Chemical Manufacturers Association (CMA) developed a set of environmental standards for all member companies to adopt and instituted a program, “Responsible Care,” in 1990. Responsible Care bound its members to a set of principles designed to improve environmental performance. The primary goal of this program was to mend the public image of the chemical industry following events such as the disaster of Union Carbide’s pesticide gas accident at Bhopal, India, in 1989, and eventually to improve member companies’ environmental reputation (Nash & Ehrenfeld, 1996). Similarly, programs designed to improve environmental reputation were flourishing in other industries, such as the Strategies for Today’s Environmental Partnership (STEP) of the American Petroleum Institute in 1990, the Encouraging Environmental Excellence (E3) of the American Textile Manufacturers Institute in 1992, the Enviromnental Management Program (EMP) 60 o: in: Pm: Prat rattan 1991. etc. t 12312 area v" Q, L ' £1.31. mhll\ bums m "Wt' ‘ ”Esme . orlendg , . Correlatio; Dag-um “1165105 . Compmic “Fitted [Hat also compilin WORD a ‘ ”“10 t1 R313}; to L of the Printing Industries of America, Inc. in 1992, the Great Lakes Automotive Pollution Prevention Project (APPP) of the American Automobile Manufacturers Association in 1991, etc. (Hoffman, 2000 a). Thus, environmental reputation is becoming more. critical in the area of business. A critical factor encouraging corporations to make stronger efforts for improving their environmental reputation is consumers’ environmental concerns related to corporate business performances. It is because consumers began to consider a corporations’ green reputation in making their purchase decision. In other words, consumers began to demand environmentally friendly attributes in products and companies.3 Another critical factor is financial market drivers. Financial investors including bankers, shareholders, and insurance companies also began to consider environmental reputation in their investment or lending decisions in order to reduce investment risks because of the possible positive correlation between environmental performance and economic practices.4 According to Dasgupta, Laplante, and Mamingi (1998), a high level of pollution intensity may signal to investors the inefficiency of the firm’s production process. “For reputationally-sensitive companies, public recognition of good or bad performance may translate to large expected gains or losses over time. These can affect lending decisions by bankers, who may also be concerned about legal or financial liability for polluters who are not complying with regulations” (Wheeler, 1997, p 8). Thus, investors began to make decisions for their financial investment based on the data about corporate environmental performance. Environmental reputation matters for firms whose expected costs or ¥ 3 Refer to the “Market Drivers” in Chapter II, p. 27. 4 Refer to the “Resource Drivers” in Chapter II, p. 23. 61 "'1, f“ 1 n TQr-ln: lain..- mra next re; Ear-merit of lilfi pUbilC Chg Pollution red; info: bum, as the Ihreat bttauSe int} Share and lo C0515 “hm litigation re ”“Smedte revenues are affected by judgments of environmental performance by customers, suppliers, and stockholders (Cohen, 1998). CEPI influences the image and reputation of related corporations. Dasgupta, Laplante, and Mamingi (1998) claimed, “If properly informed, capital markets may provide the appropriate reputational and financial incentive” (p. 5). Similarly, Wheeler and Afsah, (1996) stated, “Public knowledge of environmental performance has important implications for reputaionally sensitive companies” (p. 2) and “Good PROPER ratings will enhance business reputations with investors and consumers” (p. 4). Thus, reliable and understood information of corporate environmental performance can create strong new reputational incentives to polluters to move beyond compliance and toward attainment of higher performance ratings (Wheeler, 1997). In sum, CEPI disclosures to the public change corporate image and reputation and they would be effective for pollution reduction, especially for reputationally sensitive companies. Role of Information: Carrot and Stick Information disclosure of corporate environmental performance to the public may be seen as a “Carrot” or “Stick” approach where the carrot is the incentive and the stick as the thl’eat of enforcement. In other words, the donkey or corporations moves forward because information disclosure causes a decrease in revenue due to a shrinking market Share and loss of stock value. This in turn causes an increase of corporate management costs when boycotts by green consumers occurs, or when citizen complaints and litigation results in stronger environmental law enforcement by government and results in In - - ' ass media exposure of corporate envrronmental practice. 62 hr" '5‘ ll5§5 - «Luff-f :1 Cl“ ' A. * .‘.....u I .R; 1.; :‘H .15 ..sth. u I. o ";l"\“ " 4‘; 1n- n r I b.~.~.bl~ £5. 1 333355 0! CI .1 . 'I—r . . trad. ., f EI'OI‘. Utertompfx p. . u; \ "I6. I! 1‘ W316 foils. These potential losses and increased management costs would weaken the corporate competitive position and eventually cause them to lose competitive standing in the industry. That is, the new industrial competitive business environment is driven by corporate environmental information. Therefore, for polluters, the financial loss and increase of costs are nothing more than a stick strongly threatening their survival in their new business environment. For green firms, the relative benefit from polluters’ financial loss and increased costs are a carrot granting competitive advantages. Thus, it is assumed that the stronger the firms perceive threats, the more voluntarily they will comply or over—comply to environmental standards. The carrot and stick principle implied in the idea of PID is visually summarized into the following Figure3.1. 63 Figure 3.1. Public Information Disclosure as Pollution Control Tool: Carrot and Stick Principle of Organizational Behavior Control Environmental Information Disclosure l Public (MARKED Carrot (Prize) for Non-Polluting Stick (Threat) to Polluting Corporation Corporation Relative Benefit Loss of corporation & Brand credibility Revenue Loss: Decrease of Market Shara Financial Loss: Decrease of Stock Value \ / INDUSTRY: New Competitive Environment) Threats to Survival of Polluting Corporations Encouragement for Non-polluting corporations [\ Voluntary Compliance to Environmental Standards: Polluting Corporations Over-Compliance: Non-polluting Corporation \ 64 h“ Conceptual Fl WT. so ( pressures for o ”.‘.., 9 ... nut 2:10: or 0: market at stock talc:- “m ? ii ‘1— tt..l.01 15 L142: C01 pit .N .— .L’ J m Conceptual Framework of Public Information Disclosure When Corporate Environmental Performance Information (CEPI) is disclosed to the public in an easily understood form, the information may generate motivation5 and pressures for profit-maXimizing corporations to comply with environmental standards. The motivation and pressure for voluntary compliance basically results from potential loss of market share, potential increase of cost by threats of divers social drivers, and loss of stock value. Thus, the idea of Public Information Disclosure (PID) for pollution control is claimed to have the following content for polluting corporations: 1. CEPI can turn consumer attitude in a negative direction against the polluting corporations, and the negative attitude will decrease the demand for the products. Decreased product demand causes a loss of market share. CEPI, therefore, motivates corporations to comply voluntarily with environmental standards. CEPI motivates the public to pressure politicians, government, environmental NGOs, the community, and the market to act against polluting corporations. These pressures result in a strengthening of environmental law enforcement, increasing environmental litigation, stimulating product boycotts, and strengthening mass media exposures. The threats can constitute potential costs for the polluting corporations and the potential cost is a reason for corporations to comply voluntarily with environmental standards. CEPI influences investors to predict that the stock prices of the polluting corporations will drop because of the potential effects of negative information Economists generally use the term “incentive” rather than motivation or pressure. 65 h Nani... r...— D25; ““4" ‘3. MIL " ‘3“..‘1' ,3 Or “1.“.th such as the potential loss of market share and the increased costs of corrective action by the polluting corporations. This results in the reduction of stock value and motivates polluting corporations to comply voluntarily with environmental standards. Disclosure of CEPI for non-polluting corporations creates the opposite effect. That is, the potential increase of market shares and stock values produces the motivation or incentive for non-polluting corporations to over-comply with the environmental standards. The idea of PID is visually summarized in the following Figure 3.2: A Causation- Focused Model of Public Information Disclosure. 66 Figure 3.2. A Causation-Focused Model of Public Information Disclosure [Corporate Environmental Information disclosure by Governmentj J (Public) GOVERNMENT COMMUNITY Civil Complaints Consumer Attitude and Purchase Behavioral Change . ./ Tighter Law Law Suits Enforcement: ‘—_ Boycott by NGOs F mes/Regulations Political Pressure Direct Negotiation Mass Media Exposure MARKET INDUSTRY Effect on Stock Value Effect on Market Share Pollutin Cor orations Reputation Loss Profit Loss Financial Loss \ l Non-polluting corporations Relative Benefit ./ (IND USTR Y) Voluntary Compliance / Over-Compliance for Survival in the New Competitive Business Environment 67 Tum. ... 5k . *H- ,ar' 50:19.. t...~...\ . i .. l scram. C 3:45.) i‘H" ‘ La :5 D I M Hi 11\ It; q 'h’j - to. ”>U»ll\l pilot: for p is its first 5:.- Em; “‘h L “fists the 10“,}.de poll, it aoitude . berattoml L ahalorient, ' 1011mm Ct _r\) A “7930 (”551mm anii ‘ Three actors are at work in the framework of PID: government, public or diverse social drivers, and corporations. Government should provide highly credible and easily understood CEPI to public. CEPI disclosures may create negative attitude and behavior of the public toward polluting corporations and create positive attitude and behavior of the public toward non-polluting corporations. Then, negative attitude and behavior of public for polluting corporations or positive attitude and behavior of public to non- polluting corporations force corporations to reduce the total quantity of pollution emissions. Thus, the government’s CEPI disclosure is the initial stage, the public’s attitude and behavior change is the intermediate stage, and corporate pollution reduction is the last stage in the fi'amework of PID. Environmental information about corporate pollution disclosed to the public Changes the public’s behaviors (i.e., consumer purchase behavior or investors’ behavior) toward polluting or non-polluting corporations and the behavior changes are preceded by the attitude changes.6 The resulting is expressed in altered purchase practices, and this behavioral change creates incentives (i.e., pressure or motivation) for corporate pollution abatement. Therefore, the conceptual framework of PID can be examined in terms of the following components (Refer to Figure 3.3): 1. Development and release of CEPI to the public 2. CEPI influence on public’s negative (or positive) attitude and behavior toward polluting corporations (or toward non-polluting corporations). \ 6 Assumption about the relationship between behavior and attitude is discussed in the Chapter IV Research estion and Hypothesis. 68 3. Negative attitude and behavior toward polluting corporations causes loss of market share of polluting corporations. 4. Loss of market share or the fear of lost market share leads to corporate pollution reduction. Figure 3.3 Conceptual Framework of Public Information Disclosure GOVERNMENT PUBLIC MARKET CORPORATION CEPI Attitude & L f Pollution Disclosure Behavior 055 0 Reduction ’ Change . Market ’ Share 69 Research TI. 0. _ 1‘“wa ‘ “l‘\l\cl“\l\ no, ‘I L A 5. than”: I U "“‘-.\::; $ 0 ifi‘w in i" \u “1‘ CHAPTER IV RESEARCH QUESTIONS AND HYPOTHESES Research Questions The primary research question is: “Does corporate environmental performance information (CEPI), when disclosed to the public, influence the product market by creating incentives (i.e., pressures or motivations) for corporations to reduce their pollution?” To answer this primary question, the following three subsidiary questions have been developed: 1. Do negative CEPI disclosures generate negative consumer attitudes and behavior toward polluting corporations and, conversely, do positive CEPI disclosures cause positive consumer attitude and behavior toward non- polluting corporations? 2. Do CEPI disclosures shrink the product market of polluting corporations and, conversely, do the CEPI disclosures expand the product market of non- polluting corporations? 3. Could public information disclosure (PID) as a pollution control tool be effective in Korea? 70 Research Foctt T3315 re ..es 171 to: 'c m er The c fit‘fig- .. hue)“; "J 835 conceptual ”mama: Meow mflui‘nce tl “Otpottum Research H % Research Focus This research focuses on the causal relationship between CEPI disclosure and changes in consumer attitude and purchase behavior. An empirical approach is employed to answer the research questions. The conceptual framework of PID related to product markets is defined as follows: 1. CEPI leads consumers to develop negative attitudes and behavior toward polluting corporations and positive attitudes and behavior toward non- polluting corporations. 2. The negative or positive attitude and behavior toward polluting corporations or non-polluting corporations cause corporate pollution reduction. Based on the findings discussed in the Chapter H, the second stage of the conceptual framework has been demonstrated to be true. Now, the first stage of the conceptual framework must be examined in order to determine the truth of the conceptual framework of PID. Hence, the research focus is on the question “Does CEPI disclosure influence the public’s attitudes and purchase behavior toward polluting corporations and non-polluting corporations?” Research Hypothesis CEPi_md Attitude Change 71 “S {I ..‘I about the pol taxation. C rte-rot es the masks it. the} also b0} '30166 8; A: elect or. cor {hugged by ( Pill, CEPI c3 Attitt iFlSilbem S; that is “pre (£3318; Ci toward a SPt lime ShOUld coneSPOI‘ids [Ward bu“. Ex"mood It is hypothesized that CEPI disclosures change consumers’ attitude toward polluting and non-polluting corporations. Most PID advocates assert that disclosing CEPI to the public creates reputational incentives for pollution reduction because information about the polluting actions and practices of corporations can damage corporate image and reputation. Conversely, environmental information of non-polluting corporations improves their image and reputation. When the Exxon Valdez oil spill disaster occurred in Alaska in 1989, consumers not only developed unfavorable attitudes toward Exxon, they also boycotted Exxon products and returned thousands of the company’s credit cards (Bovee & Arens, 1992). Assuming that corporate image or reputation can have a direct effect on consumer attitude toward corporations, it is inferred that an image or reputation changed by CEPI disclosure can change consumer attitude toward corporations. Simply put, CEPI can change consumer attitude toward corporations. Attitudes directly influence behavior or influence behavior through intentions (F ishbein & Ajzen, 1975).l “Attitude is conceptually defined as a psychological tendency that is expressed by evaluating a particular entity with some degree of favor or disfavor” (Eagly & Chaiken, 1993, p. 1). According to Eagly and Chaiken (1993), “An attitude toward a specific behavior directed toward a given target in a given context at a given time should predict the specific behavior quite well because this attitude exactly corresponds to the specific behavior” (p. 167). For example, the changes of attitude toward buying Exxon products strongly influences the behavioral changes of purchasing Exxon products because Exxon event released 11 million gallons of crude oil that ' The theory of reasoned action asserts that intentions have a direct effect on behavior and attitudes have a direct effect only on behavioral intentions, not on behavior. 72 \u—‘q ”.37.th '53 m, ' E: 2‘ (it. com compost racism: 5 enconsunt cope-razor lessen at I.“ :consu: his study. ( trimming adienisem fal‘Orable. Were away, Th: dlSClosum fir“ hlpoi polluted the Alaskan coastline in 1989. Thus, attitude toward purchase behavior strongly influences the purchase behavior (or purchase intention). Even though it is not attitudes toward a specific behaviorz, attitude toward targets (i.e., corporations) also could strongly influence the behavior of purchasing products of corresponding corporations. So far, environmental studies have not provided any evidence supporting the assertion that attitude toward polluting corporations influences on consumer purchase behaviors (or purchase intention) against products of polluting corporation. However, some studies of advertising have identified the relationship between attitude toward corporations and purchase behavior. Winters (1989) suggests that consumers' attitude toward a corporation has a direct effect on brand purchasing. In his study, Chevron Corporation ran corporate commercials with the objective of improving consumers’ unfavorable attitudes toward the company. Through these advertisements, corporate credibility improved and attitude toward Chevron became more favorable. The company experienced increased brand sales among those consumers who were aware of the campaign. Therefore, based on the inference that a positive relationship exists between attitude toward corporation and purchase behavior (or intention), it is inferred that CEPI disclosure has a direct effect on the consumers’ attitude3 toward corporations. Thus, the first hypothesis is as follows: 2 Attitude toward behavior (e.g., buying Samsung Cellular phone) is a distinctly different class of attitude than the attitude toward targets (e.g., Samsung Co.). 3 Like hypothetical constructs, attitudes are not directly observable but can be inferred from observable responses. Social sciences often have assumed that people’s attitudes can be or should be divided into three classes: cognition, affect, and behavior. Thus, observable responses for attitude inference are cognitive responses, affective responses, and behavior responses (Eagly & Chaiken, 1993). 73 H1.“ CE". 351 CW ll 15.: axiom-:1: and cm iron mutation. The credibility. credibility. Someone 01 calm-alien WCClled e Hence. the Olatademic lNEWCll. 19 “Opt. and c “fined that “Mavens. images. H 1: CEPI disclosures change consumer attitude toward corporations positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. CEPLand Corporate Credibility It is assumed that CEPI disclosures change consumers’ perception of credibility about polluting and non-polluting corporations. Previously mentioned, PID advocates assert that CEPI creates reputational incentives for pollution reduction because environmental information of polluting corporations damages their image and reputation and environmental information of non-polluting corporations improves their image and reputation. The change of corporate images or reputation means the change of corporate credibility. The terms “reputation” or “image” are conceptually very similar to the term credibility. According to the definitions from Newell (1993), image is the concept of someone or something that is held or projected by the public and reputation is the general estimation by which one is held by the public. “Corporate credibility” is defined as the perceived expertise, truthfulness, and/or honesty of the firm (Mackenzie & Lutz, 1989). Hence, the term "credibility" seems to be definitionally more specific and for the purpose of academic research, more appropriate, than either of the terms "image" or "reputation" (Newell, 1993). Image and reputation, on the other hand, seem to be much broader in scope, and encompass many other dimensions including credibility. Therefore, it is asserted that CEPI disclosures influence consumers’ perception of credibility toward corporations, instead of asserting that CEPI disclosures influence corporate reputations or images. 74 H 0 . '. . l 4 ,. ihvlsul sat-“:7” a .. I EL.» 5.. "4“".7‘.’ 5M. . . u. . ‘7‘”,‘Jfl‘c 3. hiub.d..‘v.. . . . ”’1‘ k, “italic .. ""th -.‘ “din-Ml. it 'm Hui. L; :71 Ti ‘.‘c \ “Ftp: 9‘ ‘ iii ton ‘ 1 ‘1‘ w. ..‘potlfi More recently, Newell (1993) found that corporate credibility had a positive effect on attitude toward brands (i.e., corporations). Fombrun (1996) asserted that high corporate credibility is important in producing positive attitudinal changes toward a corporate advertisement and toward the brand as well as in influencing purchase intentions. Lafferty and Goldsmith’s (1999) experiment also proved that corporate credibility or reputation influences consumers’ attitudes toward brand and purchase intentions. Based on these findings and the identification of the conceptual relation among ’9 6‘ the terms “image, reputation” and “credibility,” it is asserted that CEPI disclosure influences the corporate images or reputations, and consequently changes consumer perception of credibility toward corporations. Thus, the relationship between CEPI and the consumers’ perception of corporate credibility is reflected in the following hypothesis: H 2: CEPI disclosures change the consumers’ perception of corporate credibility positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. CEPI and Purchase Intention PID advocates assert that CEPI changes consumer purchase behavior negatively for polluting corporations and positively for non-polluting corporations that in turn create incentives for corporations to reduce pollution. A number of the cases of consumer 75 u IVA-a- .< ll i..~s.-c I. v Q‘r-Op an ...‘n J» V R“ ”r ‘ l '\ v§‘51.k‘lk ‘ l u . ‘.‘w 9 121303.310 ' « Hi ‘65: Rffa s ”10' tier {0 19h; ' boycott or green consumerism support this assertion.4 Thus, the research should observe purchase behavioral change to prove the causal relationship between CEPI and behavior change. However, a number of variables influence behavior change. Therefore, constructing an experiment in which the subject shows behavioral changes caused only by the CEPI is extremely costly. The purchase behavior can be well predicted from purchase intention that is a psychological construct distinct from attitude. Intention represents the person’s motivation or conscious plan to exert effort to carry out. Purchase intention, therefore, has an effect on the purchase behavior (Eagly & Chaiken, 1993).5 Thus, it can be assumed that purchase behavior and purchase intention are comparable for the purpose of this research. Thus, the third hypothesis is developed as follows: H 3: CEPI disclosures increase consumer purchase intention for the products of non-polluting corporations and decrease consumer purchase intention for the products of polluting corporations. Hypotheses 1, 2, and 3 are illustrated in Figure 4.1. \ 4 5 Refer to “Market Drivers” in the Chapter II, p. 27. 19 efer to the Fishbein and Ajzen’s theory of reasoned action or planned behavior (Ajzen, 1985; Ajzen, F‘ 88; Ajzen, 1991; Ajzen & Fishbein, 1980; Fishbein, 1967; Fishbein, 1980; Fishbein & Ajzen, 1975; lShbein & Ajzen, 1977). 76 :1 fir?) 53;. -, '4... . x Figure 4.1. Hypothetical Diagram of the Effectiveness of CEPI on Consumer Purchase Behavior". Environmental Information V Consumer Corporate Consumer Attitude Credibility Purchase toward . to Intention Corporations Consumers Purchase Behavior Decreasing Demand for Product of Polluting Corporations Increasing Demand for Product of Non- polluting Corporations \ 6 This research does not focus on the causal relationship among the three variables but focuses on the causal relatronship between CEPI and the three variables: attitude, credibility, and purchase intention. 77 ['1'- " L—L‘ ”1 mm '3 cm i: i”;.: “my; cons. Environmental Attitude as a Moderator7 Variable The public’s environmental attitude toward pollution is assumed to influence the effectiveness of the public information disclosure as a pollution control tool because it is reasoned that the extent of changes in consumers’ purchase behavior by CEPI disclosure varies depending on the intensity of consumers’ environmental attitude toward pollution. Chan (1996) found that respondents who were more concerned about environmental issues tended to purchase more environmentally friendly products. As is well known, the movements for green consumerism or boycotts have been initiated mostly by environmentalists who apparently are high on the environmental attitude scale. Thus, it is inferred that there is a relationship between consumers’ environmental attitude and consumer purchase behavior, related to CEPI disclosure so that the fourth hypotheses is: H 4: Consumers who have strong environmental attitudes about pollution (EAP) will change the three dependent variables more than consumers who have weak EAP8. In other words, a positive relationship exists between EAP and the three dependent variables: attitude toward corporation (AC), corporate credibility (CC), and purchase intention (PI). 7 Moderator is defined as a variable that intervenes between independent and dependent variable and influences the intensity of effect in the dependent variable. However, it is neither an independent variable nor a mediator variable. Moderator variable is a special case of the masking variable. Masking variables are unknown variables that affect the defendant variable. Meanwhile, Mediator variable is defined as a middle variable located between the first and the final variable in the causal diagram so that mediator is both independent and dependent variable. For more details, see chapter VII, p. 221. 8 In this research, environmental attitude specifies the environmental attitude toward pollution (EAP) because the research is related to industry pollution. Thus, high EAP is defined as the status of a strong concern, awareness, and belief about pollution. Low EAP is defined as the status of a weak concern, awareness and belief about pollution. 78 cow It»! Or brzx Corporate F ainiliaritxfl Moderator Variabl_e There may also be a relationship between consumers’ familiarity with corporations and consumers’ purchase attitude and/or behavior changes. According to Eagle and Chaiken (1993), the amount of stored information or knowledge that is available and accessible to people (i.e., familiarityg) moderates attitude-behavior correspondence. The less information possessed by an individual, the greater the change induced by any new piece of information. Then, Eagle and Chaiken’s assertion is consistent with the finding of Lavine, Huff, Wagner and Sweeney (1998) that one with more information has a stronger and more stable attitude than one with less information. Many consumers do not change their purchase behavior even though they are exposed to CEPI because they already have strong familiarity (or preferences) for specific products or brands. Thus, the fiflh hypothesis is developed: H 5: Consumers that are highly familiar with a corporation (CFC) change consumer attitude, corporate credibility, and purchase intention less than one with low familiarity. In other words, a negative relationship exists between CFC and the three dependent variables: attitude toward corporation (AC), corporate credibility (CC), and purchase intention (PI). CEPI Credibility as a Moderator Variable The credibility of CEPI in the mind of the consumer moderates the change of consumer attitude, corporate credibility, and purchase intention. The credibility of information is a critical element for the success of the P11) program aimed to reduce 9 Additionally, for a conceptual understanding about “familiarity”, refer to Brucks (1985). 79 o“ “ LoLU .A YH‘V’j ...x.‘ 5 m--' ”nigg 'fi “v.3 um. ,, d,‘re d industry pollution. BAPEDAL (Indonesia’s National Pollution Control Agency) and NIPR (the New Ideas in Pollution Regulation: a group of the World Bank) initiated an Indonesian PID program “PROPER.” In 1995, PROPER made considerable effort to increase the credibility of information which they disclosed to the public because mistakes made in public could destroy the credibility of the grading system of CEPI. To increase the credibility of CEPI, they based the grading system upon multiple sources of data, conducted independent inspections, developed a user friendly computer program for analyzing the data, and designed a multiple step process for reviewing proposed grades before disclosing CEPI to the public. Aronson, Turner and Carlsmith (1963) found that for messages from a high credible source, there was a substantial increase in opinion change but when the source had only a moderate level of credibility, opinion change decreased. Thus, the sixth hypothesis is introduced: H 6: The greater the credibility of CEPI (CCI), the greater the effect of the CEPI rating on the dependent variables. That is, there is a positive relationship between CCI and the three dependent variables: AC, CC, and PI. 80 lntr Dar 5.. ‘ Rein LY I‘ 56?. CHAPTER V RESEARCH METHOD' Introduction The primary purpose of this experiment is to test the hypothesis that corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) disclosures change consumers’ attitude and purchase behavior negatively against polluting corporations or positively for non- polluting corporations. The experiment is designed to observe causal effects of CEPI on purchase behavior changes. Hence, CEPI is an independent variable and the dependent variables serving to predict purchase behavior are as follows: 1. Attitude toward corporation (AC) 2. Consumer corporate credibility (CC) 3. Consumer purchase intention (PI) The following three variables are moderator2 variables that are used to test hypothesis H 4, H 5, and H 6: 4. Environmental attitude toward pollution (EAP)3 5. Consumer familiarity with a corporation (CFC) 6. Credibility of Corporate Environmental Performance Information (CCI) ' Images in this dissertation are presented in color. 2 Moderator is defined as a variable that intervenes between independent and dependent variable and influences the degree of dependent variable. However, it is neither an independent variable nor a mediator variable. Masking variables are unknown variables that affect the defendant variable. Meanwhile, Mediator variable is a middle variable located between the first and the final variable in the causal diagram so that mediator is both independent and dependent variable. For more details, see chapter VII, p. 221. 3 High EAP is defined as the status of a strong concern, awareness, and belief about pollution. Low EAP is defined as the status of a weak concern, awareness and belief about pollution. 81 M, P... am 011 Experimental Design and Participants An experiment was conducted to collect data identifying the causal relationship between CEPI and consumers’ purchase behavior change. The over-arching the research design is the two-group random assignment method combined with pre-post tests in the laboratory environment (i.e., university classroom). 4 The post-test was performed approximately one week after the initial experiment (i.e., pre-test) to track individual attitude and behavior change caused by a stimulus, which was CEPI. This test was used to observe differences of individual attitude or behavior before and afler exposure to the stimuli information. Both of the two groups in the post-test were defined as treatment groups because they were provided with stimuli, but subjects in the pre-test were not given any stimuli so that subjects in the pre-test were a control group. In the post-test, each of the two groups were treated with inverse information (e. g., positive versus negative CEPI) in order to comparatively observe how the subjects responded to inverse information about the same corporations concerning corporate pollution emissions. For example, Group A in the post-test was given negative information and Group B in the post-test was given positive information about pollution emissions of Samsung Electronics Co. Three hundred six Korean undergraduate students participated in this experiment on a voluntary basis. 4 All data were collected during regular class session. A laboratory setting for the experiment was selected rather than field experiment because it is desirable to control the experimental situation and to manipulate experimental stimuli more precisely for the causation study (Wirnmer & Dominick, 1994). Therefore, subjects were invited into the laboratory (i.e., classroom) rather than having experimenter go to the subjects in a real world setting. 82 Cort ,, ‘=n-n EL. L V 1“Ir it)“. Riny lllSial Mtlf coax Prod: PTOdL exper Corporations and Products Selected The four real5 Korean corporations and their new unnamed products presented to subjects were 1) Samsung Electronics Cellular Phone Co. and its new cellular phone, 2) Hyundai Electronics Cellular Phone Co. and its new cellular phone, 3) Nongsim Ramyeun Co. and its new instant noodle, and 4) Binggrae Ramyeun Co. and its new instant noodle. Four corporations, two of which are cellular phone companies and two of which are instant noodle companies, were selected to measure attitude and credibility toward corporations. Their four new unnamed products were presented to subjects to measure purchase intention. To eliminate the influence of established brands, this experiment employed new unnamed products that were fictitious. Consumers’ purchase intention for particular products is influenced by previous knowledge, experiences, or preferences for those products. By using a new unnamed product, the influence of previous knowledge, experiences, and/ or preferences on purchase intention can be reduce. The market share of Samsung and Hyundai for cellular phones and Nongsim and Binggrae for instant noodles were almost equal at this time. Dominant market share means a pre-existing strong preference by consumers. The strong pre-exiting preference of subjects hinders constructing a strong experiment because the strong preference hinders changes of consumer purchase behavior, even though external stimuli are strong. Cellular phones and instant noodles are considerably salient for Korean university 5 Using real corporation names is expected to diminish issues resulting from the artificial nature of the experimental environment. 83 Ct students.6 Student subjects know enough about cellular phones and instant noodles to formulate meaningful estimates of brand7 attitude and purchase intention. Korean university students also are very familiar with the above four corporate names. Stimuli One of two colors ( green and red)8 was assigned to a corporation to show the status of corporate compliance with Korean national pollution standards. “Green” was assigned to Samsung and Nongsim, and “Red” was assigned to Hyundai and Binggrae for Group A in the post-test. For Group B in the post-test, “Green” was assigned to Hyundai and Binggrae, and “Red” was assigned to Samsung and Nongsim. That is, two booklets of stimuli distributed to subjects contained inverse CEPI.9 The graded CEPI was disclosed under the name of the Bureau of Environmental Policy in the Korean Ministry of Environment (KME) to increase the credibility of information provided to subjects.10 Subjects were informed that the Bureau of Environmental Policy in the KME gathered data, and rated the status of corporate compliance with the pollution standards. The meaning of the color grades of four corporations were repeatedly presented to subjects in the format of simple and colorful written sentences, a table, and a graph 6 For example, a golf club is not a salient item for Korean university students because golf is a very luxurious sport in Korea. However, according to an informal survey, most (or al most all) university students have cellular phones and almost all students frequently enjoy instant noodles. 7 “Brand name” is synonymous with “corporate name” in this study. When the brand name is more familiar to consumers than the corporate name, brand name instead of corporate name can be presented to experimental subjects. 8 A five-color grade system is used for PROPER in Indonesia to rate the extent of corporate compliance to national pollution regulation standards. This system already effectively worked without any problems in Indonesia. Therefore, the color-coded grades as an evaluation system for corporate environmental rformance is expected to work effectively in Korea. Assigned color grade is arbitrarily produced for the experiment. That is, the grades are not true. '0 The credibility of KME was known to be high for the Korean public. 84 Ca. (V. E: lrr‘ la3‘ .‘le Tale adje depicting the corporate environmental index” to help subjects easily remember the information provided in the booklets. The corporate environmental index was provided in the name of the Department of Environmental Assessment in the Bureau of Environmental Policy in the Korean Ministry of Environment (KME) in order to give subjects the understanding that the information provided to subjects was produced by scientific professionals. Two photos of industrial pollution were placed on the cover page of the booklets to attract subjects’ attention. All colors in the booklets for stimuli were color-printed. Except environmental performance information of four corporations, no other information relating to the four corporations was provided to the subjects because information not related to the environmental performance of the four corporations could be confounding variables. Except two types of CEPI (i.e., each the inverse information), all contents in stimuli material (e. g., cover photos in the front pages of two stimuli printing materials) were exactly the same. This helped remove influences from unexpected factors on dependent variables. Measures of Dependent and Moderator Variables The subjects were asked to respond to several questions. First, they were asked to rate their overall impression of the four corporations on a four- tem and 7-point, bipolar adjective scale (i.e., Semantic Differential type scale) to measure consumer attitudes ” The index was also artificial. 85 if] :4 C01 Sul lUlt‘ toward each corporation. The scales are anchored with “unreputable / reputable,” “untrustworthy / trustworthy,” “negative / positive,” and “dislike / like.”12 Second, the subjects were asked to rate their overall evaluation about corporate credibility on a four-item and 7-point bipolar adjective scale. Two of the four items anchored with “overall low quality products / overall high quality products” and with “not at all good at manufacturing / very good manufacturing” measured corporate expertise. The other two items anchored with “not at all dependable / very dependable” and with “not at all concerned about customers / very concerned about customers,” measured trustworthiness.” Third, subjects were asked how likely they would be to consider buying that product and that they would purchase it. A three-item and 7-point Semantic Differential type scale was employed. The three items were anchored by “very likely / very unlikely,” “probable / improbable,” and “possible / impossible” (Yi, 1990). The scales used for all of the three dependent variables were the same so that each variable would contribute equally to the distance measure. It was, therefore, not necessary to standardize the data. A moderate variable of familiarity that was subjective knowledge about corporations used in the stimuli was measured in the pre-test. One of two measures for subjective knowledge asked subjects to respond to the following statement: “Rate Your knowledge of this item, as compared to the average undergraduate students.” This measure was anchored by “one of the most knowledgeable / one of the least '2 Measures for attitude toward corporations was developed based on the measure used by Bruner & Hensel eds., 1992, # 29 (Boulding and Kirmani) . ‘3 Bruner & Hensel eds., 1992, # 72 (Keller & Asker). Four of six items used by Keller and Asker were adopted for the measure of corporate credibility in this experiment. 86 I"" Si. 7:1 V‘ 6.. (1g ti; knowledgeable.” The second measure asked subjects to respond to the following statement: “Circle one of the numbers below to describe your familiarity to this item.” The anchor for this scale was “Extremely Familiar / Not at all familiar.” For both measures, 7—point semantic differential scales were used (Brucks, 1985). Subjects were asked to rate their overall concern, consciousness, and belief toward Korean pollution on a 5-point Likert type scale. Eight items measuring environmental attitude consisted of the verbal and behavioral commitment, affect and cognitive dimension (i.e., knowledge about environment), and government action for environmental protection. '4 The questions for environmental attitude were not placed before the questions for three dependent variables in order to prevent subjects from guessing the experimental hypothesis fiom the measure of environmental attitude. Questions to check manipulation of CEPI were presented in the post—test because subjects received stimuli in the post-test. To assess the effectiveness of the experimental CEPI manipulation, subjects were asked whether the four corporations complied with national environmental standards “very much” or “not at all,” and whether the four corporations had severely negative or positive impacts on the environment and the health of human beings. The rating scale was a 7-point Semantic Differential type scale. Credibility of stimuli information presented by the KME name was measured on a 7-point, bipolar adjective scale, anchored by “not credible / credible” and “scientific / unscientific.” '4 See Appendix A. Questionnaire for Experimental Tests. Referring to Leeming, Dwyer and Bracken (1995), Berberoglu and Tosunoglu (1995), the measure for environmental attitude was developed for this experiment. 87 00nd Prob ”16:15 llkel) and .. All measures for variables mentioned above were sealed with a high number (e. g., 5 or 7) denoting a positive response (e.g., “like”) and a lower number (e. g., l) denoting a negative response (e.g., “dislike”). The final questions in the booklet were constructed for demographic data. They were placed in the pre-test. Demographic data consisted of “Gender,” “Age,” “Major,” “Hometown,” and “Average monthly family income.” Demographic data was additionally collected to obtain basic information about subjects. Procedures Translation and Back-Translation Test A translation and back-translation test for measurement and CEPI stimuli was conducted before implementing the pilot test to ensure reliable and valid translation from English to Korean. The original questionnaires and content of stimuli drafted first in English were translated into Korean, and then back translated into English using external translators blind to the hypotheses. As a final process, the original English and back- translated English version of the measurement and stimuli were compared to find problematic differences between them that could weaken their reliability and validity. A difference found from the translation and back-translation test was about the measure for the variable of “purchase intention,” anchored with “very unlikely / very likely,” “improbable / probable,” and “impossible / possible.” The meanings of “likely” and “probable” in the original questionnaires were back-translated into “probable” in the last process because the meanings of both terms are almost the same in Korean language. 88 Thus, “very unlikely / very likely” was translated into “not want to / want to” in the Korean version. Pilot Test The pilot test was conducted during January 2001 to achieve its three purposes: 1) manipulation check for stimuli, 2) measurement check, and 3) checking Korean wording in Korean questionnaires. Twenty five Korean Kyeung-Gi university undergraduate students participated in the pilot test. They had been at Michigan State University since December 2000 as visiting students. Their age, major, and sex were diverse. A manipulation check for stimuli confirmed that the manipulation of CEPI was successful as expected. Negative information was perceived as negatively and positive information was perceived as positively in the pilot test. Except the measure of environmental attitude, all measures were revealed to be highly reliable and valid. Exploratory factor analysis performed on the eight items for the measure of environmental attitude postulated a three-factor model so that confirmatory factor analysis based on both the posited three factors and one factor were conducted on its eight items to observe the heterogeneity (i.e., parallelism) and homogeneity (i.e., internal consistency) among the three factors or within one factor. As a result, a significant reason for the three-factor model was not found. Afier inspecting the factor loadings and errors generated from the discrepancy between the obtained and predicted correlations, it was concluded that it was not necessary to exclude any item of the environmental attitude measure. 89 Based on comments from participants, one of 8 questions for environmental attitudes was redeveloped. Except comments about an item of environmental attitude, there were no comments about the Korean wording from participants so that it was assumed that the questionnaires have no Korean wording problems in the Korean version of the questionnaires and the stimuli materials. Administration The experiment was implemented from May 17, 2001 to June 12, 2001 in the classrooms of Seoul City University located in Seoul and in the Kangwon University located in Chun-Chen15 in Korea. For the pre-test of the experiment, participants first received an “Informed Consent Form” containing assurance of confidentiality of data and statement of agreement. Participants also received an instruction asking to read each page of the booklet carefully without being allowed to turn back and without being allowed to talk to each other. In addition to the written instruction, administrators gave very detailed verbal instructions on how to complete the questionnaire. Then, stimuli booklets were randomly distributed to three hundred six participants and they were asked to write down their student ID number in the first page of the questionnaire booklets, in order to know the identification of subjects between pre-post tests. They were asked to keep the booklet face down, when the questions were finished. The post-test with the same participants was performed approximately one week after the pre-test in the same classroom during normal class-time. ‘6 '5 The city of Chun-Chen is located around 150 miles west from Seoul. '6 Time interval between pre-post tests is M (Mean) = 8.7 and SD (Standard Deviation) = 4.0 days (7 days=68. 1% and 8 days=15.5% of cases). All subjects answered to experimental questionnaires just after 90 lead“ 333;, In the post-test, two types of stimuli booklets that contain the manipulated CEPI were distributed randomly to participants and they were asked to read the booklets very carefully. Participants were asked to write down their student II) on the first page of the questionnaire booklets to figure out the participants’ identification to observe the individual differences of responses to the stimuli. They also were asked to write the type of stimuli (e.g., “A” or “B”) on the first page of the questionnaire booklets for the post- test to identify who belonged to which stimuli Group A or Group B. Other instructions given in the post-test were the same as the ones in the pre-test. Debriefing As a final step in the process, when participants finished the questions for the post-test, they received notes of debriefing saying that all the information about the four corporations given to the subjects was not true and was arbitrarily created for the experimental purposes. The debriefing also addressed the true purpose of this experiment and contained a thank you note for participation. reading a print material for stimuli in the post-test so the time interval between reading the material and answering questionnaires of post-test is constant. 91 CHAPTER VI DATA ANALYSIS AND RESULTS Data and Subject Profile Three hundred six Korean undergraduate students participated in this experiment on a voluntary basis; 469 participated in the pre-test and 439 participated in the post-test. Some students did not write down the stimuli type A or B and student identification numbers. The cases not indicating the stimuli type and student identification numbers were discarded. The final cases matched by student identification numbers totaled 306 cases. Of the total number of participants, 52.6 percent were males and 47.4 percent were females. Their ages ranged from 18 to 33 years of age (M = 21.5, SD = 2.78)‘. Most subjects were majoring in the social sciences such as: Politics (49.2 %), Business Administration (9.3%), Mass Media (8.6 %), Psychology (6.6 %) of the participants, etc. Of the 306 participants, 57.5 percent were students of the Seoul City University in Seoul, Korea and 42.5 percent of the participants were students of the Kangwon University in Choon-Chun, a small city located 150 miles west of Seoul. Three fourths of the subjects grew up in urban areas (big city = 37.2%, small city = 39.1% and rural area = 22.7%). The Family Monthly Average Income of subjects was 2,160,000 Won or approximately 1,674 US dollars (SD = 1,260,000 Won / approximately 976 US. $)’. ' M = Mean, so = Standard Deviation 2 “Won” is a unit of Korean money. The exchange rate was US. $ 1 = approximately 1,290 Won in May or June, 2001 when the experiments were conducted. Thus, most subjects would belong to a middle class in terms of Korean social economics. 92 Che bep 5110 the: Stil mtg C01] 3511 Checking Unexpected Intervention between Pre and Post-tests All subjects completed experimental questionnaires immediately after reading printed materials for stimuli in the post-test. Thus, the time interval between reading the material and answering questionnaires in the post-test is constant and very short. Therefore, the probability of unexpected factors influencing subjects’ responses to the stimuli would be low. However, probability that unexpected factors intervened between the pre and post-test exists because the time interval between pre and post-tests was on average 8.7 days. The tests were implemented from May 17, 2001 to June 12, 2001. In order to check ‘ the intervention of unexpected factors between pre and post-tests, the researcher observed negative or positive news related to the four corporations Samsung, Hyundai, Nongsim and Binggrae, which were released in several major newspapers at the national level between May 17 and June 12, 2001. Negative or positive news that could influence each subject’s attitude, credibility and purchase intention related to the four corporations and their products was not found. Stimuli Manipulation Check Stimuli (i.e., treatment) were artificially manipulated. Stimuli consisted of negative and positive information concerning the environmental performances of the four companies: Samsung & Hyundai Electronics, and Nongsim & Binggrae Ramyeun. The research is needed to check whether subjects perceived the stimuli in the same manner as the researcher intended. That is, did the subjects perceive negative information of stimuli as negative information, and positive information of stimuli as positive information? 93 A variable “stimuli” was measured with two items in a 7-point Semantic Differential type scale. One item of the measurement of stimuli asked whether the four corporations complied with national environmental standards and another item asked whether the four corporations had severely negative or positive impacts on the environment and the health of human beings3 . Subjects of A and B groups were given reverse information of each other. That is, if group A was given positive environmental performance information for Samsung, group B was given negative performance information for Samsung. When group A was given negative environmental performance information for Hyundai, group B was given with positive environmental performance information for Hyundai. Table 6.1 includes basic statistics related to the manipulation test. Table 6.1.Stimuli Type and Mean, SD and SE of Stimuli Treatment N Mean Std. Std. Error Type Deviation Mean SAMSUNG 1 154 5.4318 1.1520 9.283E—02 2 152 2.3224 1.2387 .1005 HYUNDAI 1 154 2.7370 1.2475 .1005 2 152 5.3684 1.1901 9.653E-02 NONGSIM 1 154 5.3669 1.1896 9.586E-02 2 152 2.4145 1.2067 9.788E-02 BINGGRAE 1 154 2.8961 1.3811 .1113 2 152 5.5132 1.1068 8.977E-02 - Group A was exposed to Stimuli (i.e., treatment) Type 1 - Group B was exposed to Stimuli Type 2 3 The questionnaires for stimuli is as follows: * Rate the extent to which the following corporations comply to the national pollution standards. 1. Samsung Electronics Cellular Phone Co. has complied with national environmental standards Not at all 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Very well 2. The environmental performance of Samsung Electronics Cellular Phone Co. has created on the health of human being and nature Very severe l 2 3 4 5 6 7 Very Positive Adverse effects Effects 94 T-tests suggested that manipulation of the stimuli for corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) about four corporations was successful. To check the success of manipulation, independent sample T-tests were conducted to verify statistical significance for mean differences between Group A and Group B in the variable “stimuli.” Significant differences were found for the stimuli of Samsung (M = 3.1094) (t (304): 22.74, p < .001), Hyundai (M = -2.6314) (t (304) = -18. 86, p < .001), Nongsim (M = 2.9524) (t (304) = 21.55, p < .001), and Binggrae (M = -2.171) (t (292) = -l8.30, p < .001).4 Measurement Reliability and Validity Measurements of five variables with twenty-one items were used in the pre-test. The variables were: 1. 2. Attitude toward the four corporations (four items) Credibility of the four corporations (four items) Purchase Intention toward products of the four corporations (three items) Familiarity with the four corporations (two items) Environmental Attitude (eight items) Measurements for five variables with fifteen items were used in the post-test. The variables were: 1. Attitude toward the four corporations (four items) 4 T = t-value, p = p-value, figure in a parenthesis (i.e., t (304)) is a degree of freedom. 95 2. Credibility of the four corporations (four items) 3. Purchase Intention toward products of the four corporations (three items)5 4. Stimuli for manipulation check (two items) 5. Information Credibility of Stimuli (two items) Factors of measurements and number of items (i.e. questions) of each factor are summarized in Table 6.2. Table 6.2 Factors and Number of Items (i.e., questions) Pre-Test Credibility Attitude Intention Familiarity Environmental Attitude Samsung 4 4 3 2 Hyundai 4 4 3 2 Nongsim 4 4 3 2 Binggrae 4 4 3 2 All subjects 8 Post-Test Credibility Attitude Intention Stimuli Information Credibility Samsung 4 4 4 2 Hyundai 4 4 4 2 Nongsim 4 4 4 2 Binggrae 4 4 4 2 All subjects 2 - “4” is the number of item of a factor. For example: “4 ” in the cell of “Samsung” by “Credibility” in pre-test means that the factor of Credibility of Samsung is constructed by four items. 5 Questions were the same in measuring three variables “attitude,” “credibility,” and “purchase intention” in the pre and post-test. 96 r5. . . . . ‘ US Pa 11: Confirrnatory factor analysis (CF A) 6 was performed in order to assess the uni- dimensionality of each scale (i.e., internal consistency and discrimination of each measurement) because each measurement should retain internal consistency (i.e., homogeneity) within each factor and should maintain discrimination (i.e., heterogeneity) among factors (Hunter & Gerbing, 1982). The first-order CF A set each scale toward different corporations as a factor (e.g., “attitude” to Samsung is a factor and “attitude” to Hyundai is another factor) so that the first-order CFA included 17 factors with 60 items of the pre-test and 17 factors with 54 items of the post-test (Refer to table 6.1). The second-order CFA set each scale of four corporation as a factor (e.g., setting attitude to all of Samsung, Hyundai, Nongsim and Binggrae as a factor) so that the second-order CFA included 5 factors with 60 items of pre-test and 5 factors with 54 items of post-test. The CF A by a unit of corporation was also conducted. For example, CFA for the scales used for Samsung included 5 factors (Attitude, Credibility, Purchase Intention, Familiarity, and Environmental Attitude) with 21 items in the pre-test and 5 factors (Attitude, Credibility, Purchase Intention, Stimuli, and Information Credibility) with 15 items in the post-test. g 6 A confirmatory factor analysis was conducted by the computer statistics program “CFA” (1992) developed by Mark A. Hamilton and John E. Hunter, “M-MODEL” (version 1.0, 1988) developed by Mark A. Hamilton, “PACKET” (version 1.0, 1988) developed by John E. Hunter and “HTZ (Tests of Homogeneity and Heterogeneity for Confirmatory Factor Analysis)” (version 1.0) developed by Vernon Miller and Joyce Lanning. These programs are working on MS-DOS. Dr. Mark A. Hamilton is a professor at University of Connecticut. John E. Hunter is a professor in the Department of Psychology at Michigan State University. Vernon Miller and Joyce Lanning are professors in the Department of Communication at Michigan State University. 97 23.—.33-.-.30 973.92. $.12}; .2072: 12.3323. 99...: 0.: a... —.U\...:2.:::.I. «..-—7. <..~. v L.u~u.:ut~m...~: 0.: C.- .nhagnvrwu w:3:=... 0.23..:...~U-~.~C.01L.u~:\ Hobo 3682582: .3 338 983328... we 83.35% Ho.“ 388:8 mud—Na «$0 8383 3:835 8m $5 Samoa .3 380.80 meets—obooéza .mé ES «.6 £6 035 2: 5 .33: .825: can HHS—gm 3 pogo—26p 88on «£0 05 £5 wean—no.8 macaw—obooaafi 05 55 C032 and 880pr biwzm :5 .5333». 808? 2a mmmm .3 pea—:28 macaw—atoning: - oo.H vo. mH. mo. HN. Ho. mo. oH. mo. NH. NH. «0. mo. No. HH. mo. NH. oeauHuue HeuaoaaouH>eunNH eo. oo.H me. mN. Hm. we. mo. mH. «0.- mm. Ho.- NH. mo. Nm. mo. NH. 0H. oeummaHn nuH: uuHueHHaauuuuH NH. me. oo.H oN. me. No. we. 4H.- NH. mo. mm. eo.- eN. NH. Hm. 4o. NN. .aHnmaoz nuHa NuHueHHaaeuumH mo. NN. 0N. oo.H Hm. NH. «0. NH. vN. NH. mo. HH. mN. NH. mo. mH. ON. Heeeaum nth NuHueHHHauu-cH HN. Hm. me. Hm. oo.H HH. NH. 0H.- Ne. NH. oN. «0.- Nm. NH. mH. mo. om. mannaem nuH: NuHueHHHaeuan Ho. me. No. NH. HH. oo.H NN. NH. NH.- HN. 40. NN. mo. me. 0H. wN. mo. oHeooe uneuueH oeummch uou aoHuaoueH onenouamuNH mo. mo. me. «O. NH. NN. oo.H oo. mo. mH. em. NH. mH. mN. mm. NH. 0N. oHeoou uneuaaH aHnmcoz uou aoHueouaH onenuunmuHH 0H. mH. 4H.- NH. 0H.- NH. oo. co.H NN. 4N. mo.- me. mo.- NN. mo. me. No. ocean ueHaHHou Heeeaxa u0u eoHueouaH onenousmuoH mo. eo.- mH. 4N. Ne. NH.- mo. NN. co.H Ho.- mN. «0. me. mo. mN. mH. me. oeona ueHaHHou meanaum uou aoHueouuH onenousmum NH. mm. mo. NH. MH. HN. 3. en. Hof coin mH. mm. NH. mm. mH. oe. NN. ouummafln ou opauuuudum MH. 3.. mm. mo. om. vo. em. 8.. mm. mH. oo.H No. we. mm. mm. mo. em. .5393: cu opauauufluh vo. mH. eo.- HH. eo.- mN. NH. mm. eo. mm. No. oo.H oN. Nm. mH. mm. 0N. Haven»: 0» ovauHuueuo mo. mo. 4N. mN. Nm. mo. mH. mo.- mm. NH. Na. ON. oo.H mN. Ne. 0N. mm. mauuaum ou oeauHuueum No. mm. NH. NH. 3. mm. mm. mm. mo. mm. mm. Nm. mm. oo.H mm. Hv. om. oaummnum no .HuHHHnHvouonv HH. mo. Hm. mo. mH. 0H. mm. mo. mN. NH. mm. mH. Ne. mm. co.H NN. Ne. aHumaoz uo auHHHnHeouu-m mo. NH. 40. mH. mo. mN. NH. we. mH. ow. mo. mm. 0N. He. NN. oo.H mm. Haveuhu no NHHHHaHeouUIN NH. 0H. NN. 0N. om. mo. 0N. No.- me. NN. an. 0N. mm. om. Ne. mm. oo.H masaaem uo NuHHHnHeououH NH eH mH «H NH NH HH oH m m N u m v N N H um0ut0hnm 0st Gm EOHQGW $002503 QCBM—PCOUJSHE U0u00b0mv ..MO 0—969 .mfio 58:00 5:28.80 2322: £023 .833 wEBozom 025 2: E BntmEfiSm 0.8 )~U£ 23.3.2.9FNC. v|.-.t.v:: 33.3.JLLCTV .VNV U~C~NF Eugen confluence-SHE 33030 05 wfiEZc E 33:23 2N We can v.0 .00 633. 05 E macaw—oboe 382.80 805- .N 28 H H98.“ .3 5 BNEEEHNE 05 mo 858m 05 mo 88 98:3 2: .3 N 88$ 28 H ~3on oo.H mo. mo. No. mo. NH. mo. 0H. mo. «o. mo. mo. mo. No. NH. mo. 3. 533396 5333373 mo. 8H 8.- 3. HN.- mm. 8.- om. NH..- NN. 3.- He. emf mm. Ne: He. mm..- oeummeHm no HHHfiHum-nn mo. no.1 oo.H vwf mm. mm.- Nb. Nvf mm. mm.1 bb. nmf ww. omf bb. vm.- mm. Sumac! no «ngmlnn bo. vm. vm... oo.H ww.- Nm. bm.t mm. mvf 0b. mm.- mm. Nm.- mm. wm.- mm. mm..- «avg no «ngmldn mo. Hmi mm. emf 3H 3.. ON. 3.- 3. 3.- «N. 3.- HN. mm: 3.. Ne... 0N. manna-m no HHsaHum-on NH. mm. mm.- mm. mm.- ago-H .3..- Hw. bm.- mm. mvf mm. mm.- om. mef mm. mm.- OHQOOHH ufiduunfl onugfldn How acaunouaH Gannon—Hula“ mo. 3.- NN. Nmi ON. HY- 3H 3.- 3. 3.- Nm. 3.- oN. 3.- mm. 3.- NN. oHeooa uneunnH Sumac: uou noHueouaH 3335-: OH. om. mv.- mm. 3.- am. mv.- coin mm: mm. ovf 0b. mm.- mm. mm.- Mb. bm.- OGOAQ HIHHHHHOU «$0; How GOHuflOuGH 0030.35le mo. NH..- Na. 3..- we. NN.- em. NN.- oo.H NT- Nm. 3..- mN. NN.- we. 3.- NN. 0:93 .3338 manna—um now 33:35 3335-: eo. Nb. Nm.- 0b. mm..- mm. mv.- mm. Nvf coin mm.- bb. mwf vm. vmf bb. mvf Odummflfin Ou ovfluwuudnmu mo. mm.- bb. mm.- vb. m¢.- bm. ovf bm. mm.- oc.H Hm.- mm. mm.- mm. mwf mm. adamfloz 0.... o—Xfifl-ufllvu mo. Hm. Nm.- mm. vm.- mm. wvf 0b. «v.1 bb. Hm.t coin bv.- mb. om.t mm. 3..- .nflvg O» ovfluduudlnu mo. vm.- mm. mm... Hb. mm.- 0b. mmf mb. mvf mm. b¢.- oo.H Hv.- mm. vvf mm. madam Ou Ovfluauudluu No. mm. emf mm. mm.- om. mv.- mm. mm.- vm. mm.- mb. va coin mm.- «m. mvf Gage—"m uo hudflwnwuouoldn MH. Nmf bb. mmf Vb. mvf mm. mm.- mm. emf mm. om.- mm. mm.- cc...” om..- mm. 6.3932 no enuHHHnHvouolou mo. Hm. vm.- mm. bm.- mw. mv.- Mb. va bb. av... mm. 3.- vm. om.t coin mvf «dug uo %uaddndflouuvlad H. mm:- me. mm.- 0N. mmf NN. NN.- NN. 3.- mm. 3..- mm. 3.- mm. m3..- ooH manna-Hm no .SHHHnHeduUamH on mm mm Hm on an an bu on mu w" nu an Ha on a." «H um0uuum0m 05“ GM thuomnm CO0EOD Gowns-€001.52: avg—09:00 ...VC gawk. 99 .vé 2an 9 £8 .38 BE 05 E Vm 8 3 88m $0283: 2: Son-N - 8. 8.-8.-8.-No.-wo.-8.-mo.-S.-oo. 8.-8. 8.-8.-8. why-NN.- 3333 830531683 8. Z. 8.- 8. 8.- Nm. 8.- E. 8.- 3.. 8.- S. 8.- mm. 8.- 3. 8.- ouummfim n»? 3333573 2. ma. 8.- 3. 8.- 8. NH. mo. mo. 8. NH. 8.- No. 8. ma. 8. 8. 33.82 5!. 3333583 2. 8. 8. S. No.- 2. No. 3. 3. 3. 8. 3. 8. NN. 8. Z. 3. «355m A»? 53:338.: 8. No. 8. mo. 8. 8. 8. No. NN. E. 8. 8. 3. NH. 3. 88. NN. manna—um n3: huauufiaufiunna NH. ma. mo.- 0H. Ho.- .3. .3. NH. mo.- Nw. No. NN. No.- 3‘. Ho.- bN. oo. Bacon 9533:" ouummaam you noduaouan oudnouflmINH ON. 2. 8.- NH. 8.- ON. 3. 8. 8.- NN. S. 2. No. 3. S. 8. 8. 0300: panama.“ 38982 uou noflaouan manna-Snug NH. 8. 8. 3. No. HN. 8.- 8. 8. S. No.- 3. 8.- ON. 8.- N... 8.- 23am 8.333 805$: new aoflnounn 0.3338." 8.- 8. mo. 80. 8. 8. 8. NN. mm. 8.- ma. 8. 8. 8.- 3. 8. «m. 39:— uugfioo 259:3 new 53:35 3333-8 mo. 8. 8. 8.- NH. NN. 8. 8. 8. av. 8. S. 8. mm. 8. 3. 3. 09.533 ou 3333.8 8. 8. mo. 8. 8. 88. NN. 8. NH. 8. on. 8.- 3. 8. mN. 8.- NN. E8982 3 333:: 3. mo. 8. S. 88. NN. 8. 8. 00. «N. 8. Nm. mo. om. 8. mm. mo. 8055.. 3 3332-8 8. 8.- S. 8.- ma. 88. NN. 8.- Nv. 8. NM. 8.- 8. 8. Nm. 8. 8. 98956 3 33338 3. «0. 0H. .3.- oa. mm. HH. NH. bo. mm. NH. 5. ca. mm. ma. 0N. ma. ouummaum no huaafinwvounulv E. No. 2. 8. 8. mo. NN. 8. ON. 8. mm. 8. MN. 8. «n. 8. mN. 5352 no 533305..” bH. «0. mo. mo. mo. ma. 3. mm. 0H. «N. .3. om. ma. mN. 0H. cm. 3. «avg no huwawflvouonn 2. 8.- NH. 8.- 3: S. «N. 8.- om. mo. 8N. 8.- 3. 8.- 8. No. Nm. 95955 No 3333265 In 8 Na 8 on «N «N 8N 8N 8 «N NN NN NN oN 3 3 «mow-“mom was 8m 05 5 £8on 52509 scum—280-885 .m6 2an 100 CO: pk. nu. nnv .\~ -.\ O Q O D Q I Tak sec 9: Cu :~ .3 ......\ \ § . n vIL h... Second-order factor correlations (i.e., inter-correlation among factors across corporations) in the pre and post-test are presented in the following two tables7. Table 6.68 Second-Order Factor Correlation in the Pre-test Factor 501 502 503 504 505 501 100 97 70 42 12 502 97 100 76 45 13 503 70 76 100 38 12 504 42 45 38 100 17 505 12 13 12 17 100 - The correlation “97” in the table is actually “.97.” - Factor 501= Credibility of 4 corporations: —— Samsung, Hyundai, Nongsim and Binggrae - Factor 502= Attitude of 4 corporations - Factor 503= Purchase intention of 4 corporations - Factor 504: Familiarity of 4 corporations - Factor 505: Environmental Attitude Table 6.7 Second-Order Factor Correlation in the Post-test Factor 501 502 503 506 507 501 100 122 101 54 21 502 122 100 100 58 15 503 101 100 100 65 22 506 54 58 65 100 22 507 21 15 22 22 100 7 Unfortunately, second-order correlation between factors in the pre-test and factors in the post-test is not presented because the CFA program developed by Hamilton and Hunter (1992) is incapable of handling a large size of correlation matrix with 114 items of 34factors, which are 17 factors with 60 items in the pre- test plus 17 factors with 54 items in the post-test. 8 Correlations in Table 6.6 and 6.7 are generated by program CFA. 101 l“ «U ' ¥ - The correlation “58” in the table refers to “.58.” - Factor 501= Credibility of 4 corporations: Samsung, Hyundai, Nongsim and Binggrae - Factor 502= Attitude of 4 corporations - Factor 503= Purchase intention of 4 corporations - Factor 506= Stimuli of 4 corporations - Factor 507= Information Credibility Discrimination among factors was checked based on the error matrix of factor loadings generated by a statistical computer programs HT 2 (Tests of Homogeneity and Heterogeneity for Confirrnatory Factor Analysis). At present time HT 2 is not capable of handling a size of correlation matrix with 60 items in the pre-test or/ and 54 items in the post-test, thus, HT 2 was performed by a unit of corporations in the pre and post-test separately. The following error tables of factor of loading by a unit of corporations show error rate that is the discrepancy between the obtained and predicted correlations (i.e., observed factor loading — expected factor loading). 102 \. ~ .‘ ‘1. l’ .3 9!; ... Air» -Vd A u . § u « Il‘ A‘ u. .1- us IN: as .‘.w Q; on.» a c N! ~ A «.9 wk Ga an Al... ‘1‘ Q ‘1‘ .\ 1 . \u‘s {v Table 6.8. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Samsung in the Pre-test) 1 _ _ - _ - - _ _ - _ .. .. _ - - - - 2 - _ - .. _ .. _ - - - .. _ .. - - .. _ 3 _ _ _ _ _ _ .. - _ _ _ - - - .. _ _ 4 _ - - _ _ - - - - - - .. _ _ - _ .. 5 1o 3 5 2 - — — - - - - - - - - _ - 6 1 7 13 12 - — — - - - - - - - _ - - 7 8 12 2 10 - - — - - - - - - - - _ _ 8 1o 9 4 9 - - - - - - - - - - - - _ 9 15 11 16 12 17 16 17 25 - - - - — - - - - 1o 15 15 2 2 13 10 12 5 - - - - - - - - - 11 15 16 2 4 13 1o 12 4 - - - - - — - - - 12 1 1 3 2 4 2 7 o o 2 3 - - - — - - 13 8 o 9 o 9 1 3 3 1o 6 2 - — - - - _ 14 4 7 5 2 9 1 11 13 7 2 2 12 6 - - - - 15 1 o 5 3 6 1 3 4 7 1 o 9 7 - - - - 16 3 9 5 2 o 1 3 7 10 o 2 1 2 - - - - 17 7 1o 0 3 10 6 1 3 o 5 11 5 4 — — - - 18 3 2 2 9 8 5 12 7 4 3 6 4 6 - - - - 19 o 3 8 3 1 1 4 1 1 7 7 2 2 - - - - 20 6 8 3 8 5 6 1 o 1 5 1 2 3 - - - - 21 2 5 1o 15 3 6 1o 5 1 2 2 1 o - - - - coqmunwaI-I I l I I \O I I I I 10 - - - - 11 - - - - 12 - - - - 13 - - - - 14 - - — - 15 - - - - 16 - - - - 17 - - - - 18 - - - - 19 - - - - 20 - - - - 21 - - - - - Error rate “10” in the table refers to “.10.” This rule applies to error rate of all error rate tables. - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Samsung - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Samsung - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Samsung Cellular Phone - 13 and 14: Items of Familiarity with Samsung - 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20 and 21: Environmental Attitude 103 Table 6.9. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Hyundai in the Pre-test) ...: \IQONONCDIhlenwO‘xIWF-‘U'lnb mummwaI-I I I I I I I I HI I I I I I I I I I I—II (DxlI-I'WLAJUINU'IHHNWH NHHHHI—‘l—‘I—‘HI—‘HW oxomqmmprI-Io HH H I—‘H wqumwmwOI-JU'INI—I w H Hl—l NHI—‘WNHQNI—‘NOJI—‘ONWOOD #HHomHHNNmbwwaQr-‘m wmqwqwzqwoqmmmomww owxowI-IHwMI-Iwqu quI—Imhmousoxopoo OWQIhI-‘wI-‘QNHW \Imooubmmooqow H \ll-‘U'IU'INNHUJHH H o HNI—‘I—‘LDNU'ICA l I I ,_. 1.. H HH H H (DQONU'IIbbJNH I I I I \O I I I I 10 - - - - 11 - - - - 12 - - - — 13 - — - - 14 - - - - 15 - - - - 16 - - ~ - 17 - - - - 18 - — - — 19 - - - - 20 - - - - 21 - - - - - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Hyundai - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Hyundai - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Hyundai Cellular Phone - l3 and 14: Items of Familiarity with Hyundai - 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20 and 21: Environmental Attitude 104 Table 6.10. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Nongsim in the Pre-test) (DQCDUIDUJNH NNHHHHI—‘HHHI—‘Hm I—onoooqmmthI—Io MHHWCDUIHOHwaO‘I—‘Okoubh HH mmwmhmmqr—IOHAI-Imoww \INI-‘I-‘I-‘Iwa‘JNIbIbbJI-‘WCDUI I—II—I \Ipmowooqoqqmwmmaxm mummthI-J \O 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 I-‘ I-‘H NIkaHIwaI-‘belUJIb-w OQWQmmmII-SI—‘HI-‘LDO NHWI—‘WI—‘NO‘INQNQN H mOHofi-QOOQHWOHID- WHxlmHuhI-‘OU'IU'I - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Nongsim - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Nongsim - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Nongsim Instant Noodle - 13 and 14: Items of Familiarity with Nongsim - 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20 and 21: Environmental Attitude 105 O‘HOJQWU'II-‘NNOX ...; I-‘NIthOI-‘(Dwxlh H ...: NQUIWI—‘WQW mwNHxlNOCh I I I I Table 6.11. Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Binggrae in the Pre-test) 1 - - _ _ .. .. _ _ - .. - 2 - _ - .. _ - - _ - - _ _ _ - - _ _ 3 _ _ _ _ - _ - - - _ .. .. - _ .. - .. 4 - _ - _ .. .. .. _ - - _ - _ - .. _ - 5 12 5 6 3 - - - - - - - - - _ - _ _ 6 1 2 2 4 — — - - - - - - - - _ - _ 7 5 2 2 1 — — _ - - - - - - - - _ _ 8 1 2 2 3 - — - - - - - - - - _ - _ 9 11 9 o 3 10 1 3 7 - - — - - - - _ - 10 1 1 7 7 1 8 6 o - - - - - - _ - - 11 1 2 5 5 o 6 3 4 - — - - - - _ - _ 12 4 o o 2 5 1 2 2 3 5 1 - - - - - - 13 3 1 2 3 3 2 8 5 2 2 3 - - - — — - 14 3 2 1 1 9 2 2 4 o 6 9 2 3 - - - - 15 5 2 1 6 6 o 1 1 2 3 10 13 11 - - - - 16 o 1 3 7 2 3 1 3 9 7 2 6 1o - - - - 17 1o 13 13 6 7 9 7 4 3 1 3 7 o - - - - 18 1 2 1 2 3 5 4 2 6 9 12 6 1 - - — — 19 4 2 6 8 4 7 4 5 o 4 o 3 4 - - - — 20 6 o 4 5 8 5 2 3 1 3 1 8 10 - - - — 21 4 7 5 o 2 2 4 2 3 2 4 3 1 - - - - mummbWMI-I I I I I - l, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Binggrae - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Binggrae - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Binggrae Instant Noodle - l3 and 14: Items of Familiarity with Binggrae - 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20 and 21: Environmental Attitude 106 ,__- _. 1,» 1’ p~u IF- Table 6.12 Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Samsung in the Post-test) 1 _ - - .. _ _ - - _ .. - - .. _ - 2 - - _ - - _ _ _ - .. _ _ - _ .. 3 .. .. .. .. .. _ _ _ _ _ ._ .. _. _ _ 4 - - - ._ - - - _ .. _ _ - _. _ .. 5 16 16 3 2 - - — _ - - - - - _ _ 6 11 9 6 1o — - - — - - - - - _ _ 7 15 15 5 13 - - — — _ _ _ - _ _ _ 8 14 9 2 10 - - — — _ - - _ - _ _ 9 5 8 18 19 13 15 11 16 - — - - - - _ 1o 14 13 1 1 6 6 10 6 - - - - — - _ 11 13 11 2 2 7 6 9 4 - - - - - - - 12 21 20 13 28 5 2 1 o 8 8 2 - - - - 13 22 21 11 27 5 1 1 1 8 7 o - - - - 14 5 1 5 o 5 1 5 3 o 3 3 o o - - 15 1 o 6 1 5 2 7 1 o 5 3 o 2 - - - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Samsung - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Samsung - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Samsung Cellular Phone - 13 and 14: Items of Stimuli for Samsung - 15 and 16: Information Credibility 107 Table 6.13 Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Hyundai in the Post-test) 1 _ .. .. _. .. - _ - _ .. .. .. - _ 2 .. _ - _ - - _ - _ _ _ - _ _ 3 - _ - - .. - - - _ _ - _ - _ 4 _ - _ _ - - _ - - - - ._ - - 5 12 13 9 7 - - — - - - - - - - 6 9 8 5 12 - — — - - _ _ _ - _ 7 12 8 4 11 - - - - - - - - - - 8 1o 7 1 8 - — — _ - - - _ - - 9 10 12 2 4 12 6 5 7 - — - - - _ 10 1o 7 1 2 6 3 2 2 - - - — - _ 11 9 7 1 5 10 5 3 2 - - - — - - 12 20 18 11 22 10 4 2 1 6 5 3 - - - 13 19 18 13 27 10 6 6 5 1 4 7 - - - 14 4 1 1 2 4 4 2 3 2 2 4 o 3 - 15 1 1 1 4 6 2 4 5 4 1 1 3 1 - - l, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Hyundai - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Hyundai - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Hyundai Cellular Phone - 13 and 14: Items of Stimuli for Hyundai - 15 and 16: Information Credibility 108 Table 6.14 Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Nongsim in the Post-test) H CDQO‘IU'IIbWNH 1.1 OIbwthU'lI-‘Ql—‘wm \O 1.1 10 11 12 13 14 15 H mhxlONNQONNO‘ I—‘H meoIh-aswmqw» l—‘l—l mwmmwwommpw ...: mommI-IH» oasI-awmhw \IwI-IIbtnmp moowHI—Iq 0.8.9.01 I—‘NwH I—‘NHO l I I - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Nongsim - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Nongsim - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Nongsim Instant Noodle - 13 and 14: Items of Stimuli for Nongsim - 15 and 16: Information Credibility 109 Table 6.15 Error Rate of Heterogeneity (Binggrae in the Post-test) 1 _ - _ - _ _ _ _ _ - .. _ _ - _ 2 - .. _ _ - - _ _ _ _ _ - - - _ 3 - - - - - - _ _ - - - _ _ - _ 4 _ - _ .. _ - - .. - ._ - _ .. _ _ 5 17 11 6 4 - - - — - - - - - _ _ 6 7 6 2 6 - - - - — - - - - _ _ 7 14 11 7' 11 - - - - - — - - - - _ 8 10 6 4 9 - — - - - - - - - - - 9 2 1 2 9 4 1 5 S - — - — - - - 10 10 5 1 8 2 6 0 2 — - - — _ .. _ 11 10 6 1 9 O 4 1 l - — — — - - .. 12 15 15 13 20 4 2 S 1 4 1 O - — — — 13 18 16 12 19 9 0 5 0 2 2 5 - - — - 14 5 S 1 1 2 2 O 2 2 2 O O 2 - - 15 1 0 5 6 4 1 2 4 1 2 3 1 0 - - - 1, 2, 3 and 4: Items of Credibility of Binggrae - 5, 6, 7 and 8: Items of Attitude toward Binggrae - 9, 10, 11 and 12: Items of Purchase Intention toward Binggrae Instant Noodle - 13 and 14: Items of Stimuli for Binggrae - 15 and 16: Information Credibility Error rate of Heterogeneity table 7.8 shows that item 9 (i.e. the first question for purchase intention toward samsung cellular phone) and item 8 (i.e. the fourth question for attitude of Samsung) in the pre-test generates relatively high error rate (.25) to maintain heterogeneity among factors. However, except the case of Samsung in the pre- test, items 8 and 9 in other cases of measurements in the both pre and post-test do not generate high error: Hyundai (.11), Nongsim (.04), Binggrae (.07) in the pre-test and Samsung (.16), Hyundai (.07), Nongsim (.7), Binggrae (.5) in the post-test. Therefore, this study concluded that it was not necessary to exclude items 8 and 9 from the original measurements in order to raise discrimination among factors. 110 I ‘4 . . Ul.‘\ I I L40. {:1 I" UTSS Items 12 and 13 of the scale “stimuli” generated a high error rate for discrimination among factors in Samsung, Hyundai and Binggrae of the post-test (refer to table 7.12, 7.13 and 7.15). However, the high error rate of the “stimuli” scale is not significant because the scale “stimuli” is measuring whether the experimental stimuli is successful or not and it is not all related to any scales of dependent variables. Therefore, the “stimuli” scale does not weaken the discrimination among factors of dependent variables. Internal consistencies of factors are represented by reliability coefficient “Alpha (OI)”.Standardized Alpha (a) generated by CFA for each scale in the pre and post-test is presented in the following table 6.16. Table 6.16. Measurement Reliability — Standardized OI Pre-Test Credibility Attitude Intention Familiarity Environmental Attitude Samsung .80 .90 .86 .71 Hyundai .83 .93 .90 .85 Nongsim .83 .91 .93 .62 Binggrae .88 .93 .94 .81 All subjects .68 Post-Test Credibility Attitude Intention Stimuli Information Credibility Samsung .86 .93 .92 .97 Hyundai .88 .94 .94 .95 Nongsim .91 .94 .97 .96 Binggrae .89 .91 .95 .97 All subjects .89 111 CF A revealed that all scales except two retained high reliability that is internally consistent within the factor. The two scales are “environmental attitude” (on =.68) and “familiarity” (a = .62, .71, .81 and .85). Even though the reliability of these scales is not strong, the validity of the two scales is strong because they maintain high discrimination among factors (refer to table 7.8, 7.9, 7.10 and 7.11). Considering the point that validity is a relatively more important criterion for a healthy measurement than reliability, it is concluded that these two scales are still usefill measurements for this research. In summary, the original measurements used in the pre-test and post-test retains high discrimination among factors (i.e., validity) and high internal consistency within factor (i.e., reliability). The results of CFA suggested that the data were fitted with the posited construct models for pre-test measurements and for post-test measurements. Inspection of the factor loadings and errors produced from the discrepancy between the obtained and predicted correlations resulted in no exclusion of items. Statistics for Data Analysis Changes of attitude toward four corporations, credibility of corporations, and purchase intension toward products (i.e., three major variables) afier stimuli were measured. The four corporations were Samsung Electronics Cellular Phone Co., Hyundai Electronics Cellular Phone Co., Nongsim Ramyeun Co. and Binggrae Ramyeun Co.9 The new cellular phone products of Samsung and Hyundai were unnamed, as were the new 9 Samsung Electronics Cellular Phone Co. is denoted by Samsung, Hyundai Electronics Cellular Phone Co. is denoted by Hyundai, Nongsim Ramyeun Co. is denoted by Nongsim and Binggrae Ramyeun Co. is denoted by Binggrae. 112 instant noodles products of Nongsim and Binggrae“). Stimuli were negative or positive information of the four corporations’ environmental performances (i.e., CEPI: corporate environmental performance information). The Within Subjects Analysis was performed to investigate individual changes of three major variables. A Paired Samples T-test” was performed to gain 1) raw mean scores of individual changes of three major variables (i.e., gain score = score afier stimuli — score before stimuli), 2) one-directional confidence interval for the gain scores at 95 % level, and 3) one-tailed significance for the gain scores at a =.05. Three major variables were measured on the 7-point scale. For a stimuli (i.e., treatment) effect size of three major variables, stimuli (i.e., treatment) correlation and one-sided confidence interval of stimuli correlation at 95 % level was calculated by the statistical computer program “Within (Within Subjects Analysis, 1995 version)”.” When a directional hypothesis is tested, the Inference Probability makes sense. Inference probability (IP) for these research hypotheses were gained by the “Within.” IP is the probability that an effect occurs in the hypothesized direction. In other words, IP is the probability that the directional hypothesis is correct. Thus, if a directional hypothesis is positive, [P is the probability of rho (i.e. correlation of population) being positive (i.e., P (p > 0)). If a directional hypothesis is negative, IP is the probability of rho being negative (i.e., P (p < 0)). The inverse concept to IP is referred to as Reverse Probability (RP). RP is the probability that the effect occurs in the opposite direction to hypothesis. In order words, The RP is the probability that the directional hypothesis is incorrect. '0 The unnamed new cellular phones of Samsung and Hyundai are denoted by Samsung cellular phone and Hyundai cellular phone. The unnamed new instant noodles of Nongsim and Binggrae are denoted by Nongsim instant noodle and Binggrae instant noodle. ” It was conducted by a statistical computer program “SPSS” version 10.0. '2 “Within” was developed by John E. Hunter. 113 Thus, RP is 1 minus IP (RP = 1 — IP) because the probability ranges from 0 to 1. For example, If [P is .85, RP is .15 (1.0 -.85). For an interpretation of IP, this study follows the suggestions from Ralph Levinel3 : Table 6.17. Interpretation of Inference Probability Inference Probability (IP) Interpretation .667 IP Probably in the direction predicted .333 (1/3) [P < .667 (2/3) Too close to call* and Wait for further studies to confirm the hypothesis IP < .333 Probably not in the direction predicted "‘ The sample size is not large enough to conclude whether stimuli effect is in the direction predicted.l4 The stimuli (i.e., treatment) correlations were corrected for measurement error through considering measurement reliabilities of Time 1 (Pre-test) and Time 2 (Post- test). '5 This correction was conducted through the “Withinw.” Thus correlation reported '3 Levine’ suggestions about an interpretation of IP is cited from his unpublished paper “Messing Again With the Correlation: Inference Techniques And the Mysterious Inference Probability (Revised 7/24/98). Ralph Levine was a professor in the department of Psychology and is a professor in the department of Resource Development at Michigan State University. '4 The idea of inference probability comes from unpublished papers by Dr. John E. Hunter and Ralph Levine. John E. Hunter is a professor in the Department of Psychology, and Ralph Levine was a professor in the department of Psychology and is a professor in the department of Resource Development at Michigan State University. For more detail on inference probability, refer to Appendix D. Inference Probability. '5 Standardized reliability was used for correction. '6 The “Within” program describes corrections for measurement as follows: “The variance in gain scores may or may not be evidence of an interaction. Either all or a large portion of the apparent individual differences in gain may be caused by error of measurement rather than variation in the stimuli effect.” 114 in this study is corrected stimuli (i.e., treatment) correlation coefficient. Basic interpretational wording for the stimuli effect size in this paper follows the following rules: 1) Very Small or Very Weak: 0 < r < 0.1, 2) Small or Weak: 0.1 S r < 0.2, 3) Moderate: 0.2 S r < 0.3, 4) Large or Strong : 0.3 S r < 0.4 and 5) Very Large or Very Strong: 0.4 S r. Between groups analysis (i.e., group mean comparison) also was performed to compare attitude, credibility, and purchase intention changes after stimuli at the group level using Independent Samples T-test”. One group was exposed to positive CEPI and another was negative CEPI in the post-test. An independent sample t-test was conducted to test the statistical significance at a =.05 and two-tailed level for group mean comparison of three major variables. Attitude toward Corporation Hypothesis for attitude toward corporation (Hypothesis One: H1) posited that CEPI disclosures change consumer attitude toward corporations positively for non- polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. Basic descriptive statistics related to the variable “attitude toward four corporations” are summarized in the following table 6.17. Stimuli effects of attitude toward four corporations are summarized in the table 6.18. '7 It was conducted by a statistical computer program “SPSS” version 10.0. 115 Table 6.18. Descriptive Statistics of Attitude toward Four Corporations GroupA Samsung Pre-test Mean 5.36 5.31 SD .95 .99 Post-test Mean 5.60 4.28 SD 1.06 1.33 D Mean .24 -1.03 SD .92 1.23 N 154 151 Hyundai Pre-test Mean 3.90 3.94 SD 1.10 .98 Post-test Mean 3.35 4.53 SD 1.27 .98 D Mean -.55 .59 SD 1.04 1.07 N 154 152 Nongsim Pre-test Mean 5.59 5.59 SD .89 .79 Post-test Mean 5.70 4.08 SD 1.10 1.30 D Mean .11 -1.50 SD 1.06 1.37 N 151 152 Binggrae Pre-test Mean 4.24 4.13 SD .88 1.00 Post-test Mean 3.51 4.74 SD 1.21 .86 D Mean -.73 .61 SD 1.05 1.03 N 149 152 - SD = Standard Deviation - D = Gain Score (Gain score of post-test — Gain score of pre-test) - N = Sample size 116 Table 6.19 Attitude Changes toward Four corporations Group D t Sig 95% CI ofD (1-tailed) r 95% CI ofr(1-tailed) IP Lower Upper Lower Upper Samsung A: + .24 3.28 .001 .12 7.00 .12 -.01 1 .94 Samsung 8: - -1.03 -10.28 .000 -7.00 -.86 -.42 -1 -.31 1.00 Hyundai 8: + .59 6.81 .000 .45 7.00 .30 .18 1 1.00 Hyundai A: - -.55 -6.57 .000 -7.00 -.41 -.23 -1 -.11 1.00 Nongsim A: + .11 1.29 .100 -.03 7.00 .06 -.08 1 .76 Nongsim B: - -1.50 -13.52 .000 -7.00 -1.32 -.59 -1 -.51 1.00 Binggrae B: + .61 7.35 .000 .48 7.00 .33 .21 1 1.00 Binggrae A: - -.73 -8.46 .000 -7.00 -.59 -.34 -1 -.22 1.00 - A = Group A that had type A of stimuli in the post-test - B = Group B that had type B of stimuli in the post-test - "+" = Positive information of corporate environmental performance II II = Negative information of corporate environmental performance - D = mean of raw gain score (Gain score = gain score after stimuli - gain score before stimuli) - r = Point estimate of stimuli correlation coefficient - IP (Inference Probability) = Probability that effect occurs in the hypothesized direction. - Sig = p—value 117 Attitude toward Siamsung18 The direction and degree (i.e., size) of attitude changes in raw score by negative and positive CEPI stimuli are visualized in the following Figure 6.1. Figure 6.1. Attitude Change toward Samsung Attitude Change (Samsung) A 7.00 2 3 6.00 #4 " 6.00 R 8 4 00 \ +Gr0Up A V ' *- § 3.00 Gm“? B 2 ,5 2.00 < 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 5.36 5.60 + Group B 5.31 4.28 - Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. - Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual attitude change toward Samsung caused by negative CEPI (i.e., gain score) was significant: Dw = -1.03, t (150) = -10.28, p < .001, and CI = -7 to - .86.The degree of attitude change (i.e., stimuli effect size) from negative CEPI is very strong: r = -.42, CI = -1 to -.31.The probability that attitude change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. ‘8 Dw = raw mean gain score within subjects, t= t-value from t-test, p = p-value, r = stimuli (i.e., treatment) correlation coefficient, CI = confidence interval, P1 = inference probability, and Db = difference between groups 118 The attitude gain score for Samsung by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .24, t (153) = 3.28, p = .001, and CI = .12 to 7. The effect size of attitude by positive CEPI is small: r = .13, CI = -.01 to 1.The probability that attitude change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 94 percent: IP = .94. The group mean difference of attitude toward Samsung between two groups that had opposite information of stimuli each other is also significant: Db= 1.27, t (277) =10.22 and p < .001. The subjects responded to negative CEPI more strongly (r = -.42) than positive CEPI (r = .12). The data are strongly consistent with H 1. It was statistically significant that subjects’ attitudes toward Samsung changed negatively when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed positively when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The extent of the attitude change caused by the negative was very strong but the extent of the attitude change caused by positive CEPI was small. The probability that consumers change their attitude to the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent and change their attitude in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 94 percent. As a result, it can be concluded that the H 1 is strongly confirmed in the case of consumer attitude toward Samsung. Attitude towzflHvundai The direction and degree of attitude changes in raw score by negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.2. 119 Figure 6.2. Attitude Change toward Hyundai Attitude Change (Hyundai) 7.00 E 6.00 8 ; 5.00 E +Group A g 4.00 < +Gmup B Z: 3.00 8 2.00 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 3.90 3.35 —a— Group B 3.94 4.53 - Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual attitude change toward Hyundai caused by negative CEPI was significantsz = -.55, t (153) = -6.57, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.41. The degree of attitude change (i.e., effect size) from negative CEPI is moderate: r = -.23, CI = -1 to -.11. The probability that attitude change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. The attitude gain score for Hyundai by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .59, t (151) = 6.81, p < .001, and CI = .45 to 7. Effect size of attitude by positive CEPI was substantial: r = .30, CI = .18 to 1. The probability that attitude change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. 120 The group mean difference in attitude between the two groups that had opposite information of stimuli is also significant: Db= 1.14, t (304) =9.46 and p < .001. In contrast to the case of Samsung, the subjects were a little more responsive to positive CEPI (r = .30) than to negative CEPI regarding Hyundai (r = -.23). The data are strongly consistent with H 1. It was statistically significant that the subjects’ attitudes toward Hyundai changed negatively when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed positively when subjects were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of attitude change (i.e., stimuli effect size) caused by the negative and positive CEPI are moderate and substantial. The probability that consumers change their attitude in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent and change their attitude in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is also 100 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that the Hypothesis One is strongly confirmed in the case of consumer attitude toward Hyundai. Attitude toward Nongsim The direction and degree of attitude changes in raw score by negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.3. 121 Figure 6.3. Attitude Change toward Nongsim Attitude Change (Nongsim) 2:: o , fl 8 6 00 \ E p 4.00 \ + Group A v ' + g 3.00 Group 8 § 2.00 “ 1.00 Pre—test Post-test + Group A 5.59 5.70 + Group B 5.59 4.08 - Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. - Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual attitude change toward Nongsim caused by negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -1.50, t (151) = -13.52, p < .001, and CI = -7 to —1.32. The degree of attitude change (i.e., stimuli effect size) from negative CEPI is very strong: r = -.59, CI = -1 to -.51. The probability that attitude change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. The attitude gain score for Nongsim by positive CEPI was barely significant at the level of or = 0.05 and one-tailed significance test: Dw = .11, t (150) = 1.29, p = .100, and CI = -.03 to 7. The stimuli effect size of attitude by positive CEPI was also very small: r = .06, CI = -.08 to 1. The probability that change in attitude caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is not strong: IP = .76. 122 The group mean difference in attitude toward Nongsim between the two groups that had opposite information of stimuli is also significant: Db= 1.61, t (284) =11.48 and p < .001. Consistent with the case of Samsung, subjects responded to negative CEPI much more strongly (r = -.59) than positive CEPI (r = .06). The data are consistent with H 1. It was statistically significant that subjects’ attitude toward Nongsim became negative when they were exposed to negative CEPI and became positive when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of attitude change (i.e., effect size) caused by the negative CEPI is very strong and the probability that consumers change their attitude in the negative direction when exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent. The degree in credibility change caused by the positive CEPI is very small. However, the probability that consumers change their perception of credibility in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is strong (IP = .76), meaning that the effect probably occurs in the direction predicted. Meanwhile, the result from the two-group comparison revealed that raw mean gain scores of two groups are significantly different. Therefore, it can be concluded that in the case of consumer attitude for Nongsim, the H 1 is confirmed in the case of both negative CEPI disclosure and positive CEPI disclosure. Attitude toward Binggrae The direction and degree of attitude changes in raw score by negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.4. 123 Figure 6.4. Attitude Change toward Binggrae Attitude Change (Binggrae) 7.00 g 6.00 I» 5.00 2' ° \ -+- Group B 2 3.00 2 35 2.00 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 4.24 3.51 + Group B 4.13 4.74 - Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual attitude change toward Binggrae caused by negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -.73, t (148) = -8.46, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.59. The degree of attitude change by negative CEPI is strong: r = -.34, CI = -1 to -.22. The probability that attitude change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. The attitude gain score for Binggrae by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .61, t (151) = 7.35, p < .001, and CI = .48 to 7. The degree of attitude change from positive CEPI is also strong: r = .33, CI = .21 to 1. The probability that attitude change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. 124 The group mean difference in attitude toward Binggrae between the two groups that were given Opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.61, t (299) =11.20 and p < .001. Subjects responded to negative CEPI (r = -.34) and positive CEPI (r = .33) in the almost equal intensity. The data are strongly consistent with H 1. It was statistically significant that subjects’ attitudes toward Binggrae became negative when they were exposed to negative CEPI and became positive when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of attitude change caused by the both negative and positive CEPI is substantial. The probability that consumers change their attitude in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent and change their attitude in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 100 percent. As a result, it can be concluded that H1 is strongly confirmed in the case of attitudes toward Binggrae. Credibility of Corporation The hypothesis for credibility about corporation (Hypothesis Two: H2) posited that CEPI disclosures change consumer corporate credibility positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. Basic descriptive statistics related to the variable “credibility of four corporations” are summarized in the following Table 6.19. Stimuli (i.e., Treatment) effects of credibility of four corporations are summarized in the Table 6.20. 125 Table 6.20. Descriptive Statistics of Credibility for Four Corporations GroupA GroupB Samsung Pre-test Mean 5.21 5.14 SD .80 .87 Post-test Mean 5.59 4.33 SD .95 1.12 D Mean .38 -.81 SD .82 1.10 N 154 151 Hyundai Pre-test Mean 3.99 3.99 SD .98 .88 Post-test Mean 3.41 4.61 SD 1.14 .84 D Mean -.57 .62 SD 1.00 .93 N 154 152 Nongsim Pre-test Mean 5.34 5.31 SD .86 .75 Post-test Mean 5.62 4.10 SD 1.05 1.19 D Mean .28 -1.21 SD 1.04 1.21 N 154 152 Binggrae Pre-test Mean 4.20 4.17 SD .84 .89 Post-test Mean 3.53 4.72 SD 1.18 .84 D Mean -.67 .55 SD 1.16 .90 N 153 152 - SD= Standard Deviation - D= Gain Score (Gain score of post-test — Gain score of pre-test) - N= Sample size 126 Table 6.21 Credibility Changes of Four Corporations Group D T Sig 95% CI ofD(1-tailed) r 95% CI ofr(1-tailed) lP Lower Upper Lower Upper Samsung A: + .38 5.71 .000 .27 7.00 .23 .10 1 1.00 Samsung 8: - -.81 -9.03 .000 -7.00 -.66 -.41 -1 -.30 1.00 Hyundai 8: + .62 8.21 .000 .50 7.00 .38 .26 1 1.00 Hyundai A: - -.57 -7.13 .000 -7.00 -.44 -.28 -1 -.15 1.00 Nongsim A: + .28 3.30 .001 .14 7.00 .15 .02 1 .97 Nongsim B: - -1.21 -12.35 .000 -7.00 -1.05 -.55 -1 -.46 1.00 Binggrae B: + .55 7.58 .000 .43 7.00 .33 .21 1 1.00 Binggrae A: - -.67 -7.19 .000 -7.00 -.52 -.33 -1 -.21 1.00 - A = Group A that had type A of stimuli in the post-test - B = Group B that had type B of stimuli in the post-test - "+" = Positive information of corporate environmental performance - "-" = Negative information of corporate environmental performance - D = mean of raw gain score (Gain score = gain score afier stimuli - gain score before stimuli) - r = Point estimate of stimuli correlation coefficient - IP (Inference Probability) = Probability that effect occurs in the hypothesized direction. - Sig = p-value Credibility of Samsung The direction and extent (i.e., size) of credibility changes in raw score by negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.5. 127 Figure 6.5. Credibility Change for Samsung Credibility Change (Samsung) 1.: 7.00 § 6.00 W 3 5.00 2 \x + Group A S 4.00 ‘7‘“ Gro B g 3.00 ”p g 2.00 0 1.00 Pre-test Post-test ""' Group A 5.21 5.59 +GroggB 5.14 4.33 - Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. - Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data are raw scores The individual change of perception of credibility about Samsung caused by negative CEPI (i.e., gain score) was significant: Dw = -.81, t (150)= -9.03, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.66. The degree of credibility change (i.e., stimuli effect size) by negative CEPI is strong: r = -.41, CI = -1 to -.30. The probability that credibility change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. The credibility gain score for Samsung by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .38, t (153) = 5.71, p < .001, and CI = .27 to 7. Effect size ofcredibility bypositive CEPI is moderate: r = .23, CI = .10 to 1. The probability that the change in credibility caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. 128 The group mean difference in credibility about Samsung between the two groups that were presented with opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.18, t (277) =10.66 and p < .001. Subjects responded to negative CEPI more strongly (r = -.41) than positive CEPI (r = .23). The data are strongly consistent with H 2. It was statistically significant that subjects changed negatively their perception of credibility about Samsung when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed positively their perception of credibility when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The extent of credibility change caused by the negative and positive CEPI was strong and moderate. The probability that consumers change their perception of credibility to the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent and change them in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 100 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that H 2 is strongly confirmed in the case of credibility for Samsung. Credibility of Hyundai The direction and extent of credibility changes in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.6. 129 Figure 6.6. Credibility Change for Hyundai Credibility Change (Hyundai) 1? 7.00 § 6.00 z . g 5 00 p____ + Group A S 4.00 - ——————1 +6 8 g 3.00 “NP 3 2.00 o 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + GroupA 3.99 3.41 + Group B 3.99 4.61 — Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual change of perception of credibility about Hyundai caused by negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -.57, t (153)= -7.13, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.44. The degree of credibility change (i.e., effect size) by negative CEPI is moderate: r = -.28, CI = -1 to -.15. The probability that credibility change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. Credibility gain score for Hyundai by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .62, t (151) = 8.21, p < .001 and CI = .50 to 7. Effect size of credibility by positive CEPI was large: r = .38, CI = .26 to 1. The probability that the credibility change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. 130 The group mean difference in credibility between the two groups that had opposite information of stimuli is also significant: Db= 1.20, t (304) =10.81 and p < .001. The difference with the case of Samsung is that subjects responded more strongly to positive CEPI (r = .38) than to negative CEPI of Hyundai (r = -.28). The data are strongly consistent with H 2. It was statistically significant that subjects reduced their perception of credibility about Hyundai when they were exposed to negative CEPI and increased their perception of credibility when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The extent of credibility change caused by the negative and positive CEPI was moderate or strong. The probability that consumers change their perception of credibility in the negative direction when they are exposed to negative CEPI is 100 percent and change them in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is also 100 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that H 2 is strongly confirmed in the case of consumer’s perception of credibility for Hyundai. Credibility of Nongsim The direction and extent of credibility changes in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are visualized in the following Figure 6.7. 131 Figure 6.7. Credibility Change for Nongsim Credibility Change (Nongsim) 2:; 7.00 3 6.00 H 3 5.00 K + g 4 00 \ Group A ' +- g 3.00 Group B ’3 2.00 o 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 5.34 5.62 +Group B 5.31 4.10 - Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. - Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data are raw scores The individual perception change of credibility about Nongsim caused by negative CEPI was significantsz = -1.21, t (151) = -12.35, p < .001, and CI = -7 to — 1.05. The degree of credibility change (i.e., effect size) from negative CEPI is very strong: r = -.55, CI = -1 to -.46. The probability that credibility change caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. The credibility gain score for Nongsim by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .28, t (153) = 3.30, p = .001, and CI = .14 to 7. The stimuli effect size of credibility by positive CEPI was small: r = .15, CI = .02 to 1, but the probability that credibility change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is very strong: [P = .97. 132 The group mean difference (i.e., two group comparison) of credibility about Nongsim between two groups that had been presented with opposite information is significant: Db= 1.49, t (296) =11.56 and p < .001. Consistent with the case of Samsung, subjects responded to negative CEPI more strongly (r = -.55) than positive CEPI (r = .15). The data are strongly consistent with H 1. It was statistically significant that subjects’ perception of credibility for Nongsim became negative when they were exposed to negative CEPI and became positive when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of attitude change (i.e., effect size) caused by the negative CEPI is very strong and the probability that consumers change their perception of credibility in the negative direction when exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent. While, the degree of credibility change caused by the positive CEPI is weak, but the probability that consumers change their perception of credibility in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 97 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that the H 2 is strongly confirmed in the case of consumer perception of credibility for Nongsim. Credibilifl of Binggrae The direction and extent of credibility changes in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.8. 133 Figure 6.8. Credibility Change for Binggrae Credibility Change (Binggrae) 3.. 7.00 2 § 6.00 3 5.00 g 4 00 K/ + Group A .3." ' \K + Group B S 3.00 E 2.00 o 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 4.20 3.53 + Group B 4.17 4.72 - Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The individual perception change of credibility about Binggrae caused by negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -.67, t (152) = -7.19, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.52. The degree of change in credibility (i.e., effect size) caused by negative CEPI was strong: r = -.33, CI = -1 to -.21. The probability that change in credibility caused by the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. The credibility gain score for Binggrae resulting from positive CEPI was significantsz = .55, t (151) = 7.58, p < .001, and CI = .43 to 7. Effect size of credibility by positive CEPI was large: r = .33, CI = .21 to 1. The probability that the change in credibility caused by the poSitive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. 134 The group mean difference in credibility about Binggrae between the two groups that were given opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.23, t (286) =10.33 and p < .001. Subjects responded to negative CEPI (r = -.33) and positive CEPI (r = .33) in the equal intensity. The data are strongly consistent with H 2. It was statistically significant that subjects reduced their perception of credibility change about Binggrae when they were exposed to negative CEPI and increased them when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of credibility change caused by the both negative and positive CEPI is strong. The probability that consumers change their perception of credibility in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent and change their perception of credibility in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is also 100 percent. As a result, it can be concluded that H 2 is strongly confirmed in the case of credibility for Binggrae. Purchase Intention toward Products The hypothesis for purchase intention toward products (Hypothesis Three: H 3) posited that CEPI disclosures increase consumer purchase intention for the products of non-polluting corporations and decrease consumer purchase intention for the products of polluting corporations. Basic descriptive statistics related to the variable “purchase intention toward products of the four corporations” are summarized in the following Table 6.21. Stimuli effects of purchase intention toward four products are summarized in the Table 6.22. 135 Table 6.22. Descriptive Statistics of Purchase Intention GroupA Samsung Pre-test Mean 4.68 4.73 SD 1.33 1.35 Post-test Mean 5.1 1 3.84 SD 1.23 1.76 D Mean .43 -.89 SD 1.26 1.56 N 151 152 Hyundai Pre-test Mean 3.04 3.04 SD 1.28 1.24 Post-test Mean 2.79 4.10 SD 1.32 1.39 D Mean -.25 1.06 SD 1.16 1.38 N 151 152 Nongsim Pre-test Mean 5.54 5.66 SD 1.19 1.06 Post-test Mean 5.69 4.00 SD 1.14 1.61 D Mean .15 -1.66 SD 1.19 1.86 N 153 151 Binggrae Pre-test Mean 4.19 4.29 SD 1.25 1.43 Post-test Mean 3.49 4.82 SD 1.44 1.14 D Mean -.70 .53 SD 1.38 1.47 N 153 151 - SD = Standard Deviation - D = Gain Score (Gain score of post-test — Gain score of pre-test) - N = Sample size 136 Individual Purchase Intention Changes toward Four Products Table 6.23 Group D t Sig 95% CI of D (Hailed) r 95% CI of r (1 -tailed) IP Lower Upper Lower Upper Samsung A: + .43 4.17 .000 .26 7.00 .18 .05 1 .99 Samsung 8: - -.89 -7.01 .000 -7.00 -.68 -.28 -1 -.16 1.00 Hyundai 8: + 1.06 9.50.000 .83 7.00 .39 .27 1 1.00 Hyundai A: - -.25 -2.64 .004 -7.00 -.09 -.10 -1 .03 .89 Nongsim A: + .15 1.52 .066 -.01 7.00 .06 -.07 1 .79 Nongsim B: - -1.66 -10.98 .000 -7.00 -1.41 -.53 -1 -.44 1.00 Binggrae B: + .53 4.43 .000 .33 7.00 .21 .08 1 1.00 Mme A: - -.70 -6.33 .000 -7.00 -.52 -.26 -1 -.14 1.00 - A = Group A that had type A of stimuli in the post-test - B = Group B that had type B of stimuli in the post-test - "+" = Positive information of corporate environmental performance - "-" = Negative information of corporate environmental performance - D = mean of raw gain score (Gain score = gain score after stimuli - gain score before stimuli) - r = Point estimate of stimuli correlation coefficient -'IP (Inference Probability) = Probability that effect occurs in the hypothesized direction. - Sig = p—value Purchase Intention toward Samsung Cellular Phone The direction and extent of change in purchase intention in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.9. 137 Figure 6.9. Purchase Intention Change toward Samsung Cellular Phone Purchase Intention Change (Samsung) .. 7.00 2 § 6.00 z E 5.00 <9 C o —a— Group A -.-. 4.00 E; N —7<— Group B 5 3.00 8 g 2.00 3 e 1.00 Pre-test Post-test + Group A 4.68 5.11 —7<— Group B 4.73 3.84 - Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. — Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The changes in individual purchase intention toward the Samsung cellular phone related to negative CEPI (i.e., gain score) was significant: Dw = -.89, t (151) = -7.01, p < .001, and CI = -7 to -.68. The degree of change in purchase intention resulting fi'om negative CEPI (i.e., effect size) was moderate: r = -.28, CI = -1 to -.16. The probability that changes in purchase intention related to negative CEPI occur in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. The gain score in purchase intention for Samsung cellular phone resulting from positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .43, t (150) = 4.17, p < .001, and CI = .26 to 7. Effect size of purchase intention by positive CEPI is small: r = .18, CI = .05 to 1. 138 However, the probability that purchase intention change caused by the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is 99 percent: IP = .99. The group mean difference in purchase intention toward Samsung cellular phone between the two groups that were presented with opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.31, t (289)=8.07 and p < .001. Subjects responded to negative CEPI more strongly (r = -.28) than positive CEPI (r = .18). The data are strongly consistent with H 3. It was statistically significant that the subjects changed their purchase intention negatively toward Samsung cellular phone when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed their purchase intention positively toward Samsung cellular phone when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of purchase intention change related to the negative information was moderate and the probability that consumers would change their purchase intention in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent. The extent of change in purchase intention resulting from positive CEPI is small, but the probability that consumers change their purchase intention in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 99 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that H 3 is strongly confirmed in the case of consumer purchase intention toward Samsung cellular phone. Purchase Intention towafrd Hyundai Cellular Phone The direction and extent of change in purchase intention in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are visualized in the following Figure 6.10. 139 Figure 6.10. Purchase Intention Change toward Hyundai Cellular Phone Purchase Intention (Hyundai) 9 § 7.00 E, 6.00 2’ 5.00 G A O E 4.00 A —7<— roup o + Group B *_a 3.00 — 8 2.00 (U f, 1.00 5 Pre-test Post-test n. —-,<— Group A 3.04 2.79 —a— Group B 3.04 4.10 - Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The change in individual purchase intention toward Hyundai cellular phone related to negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -.25, t (150) = -2.64, p = .004, and CI = - 7 to -.09. The degree of purchase intention change (i.e., effect size) resulting from negative CEPI is small: r = -.10, CI = -1 to -.03. The probability that changes in purchase intention change resulting from the negative CEPI occur in the negative direction is 89 percent: IP = .89. The gain score in purchase intention for Hyundai cellular phone resulting from positive CEPI was significant: Dw = 1.06, t (151) = 9.50, p < .001, and CI = .88 to 7. Effect size of purchase intention by positive CEPI is large: r = .39, CI = .27 to 1. The 140 probability that changes in purchase intention change resulting from positive CEPI occur in the positive direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. The group mean difference in purchase intention between two groups that were presented with opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.31, t (301) = 8.96 and p < .001. In contrast to the case of Samsung, the subjects responded a little more strongly to positive CEPI (r = .39) than to negative CEPI for Hyundai (r = -.10). The data is strongly consistent with H 3. It was statistically significant that the respondents changed their purchase intention negatively toward Hyundai cellular phone when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed their purchase intention positively toward Hyundai cellular phone when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The extent of change in purchase intention related to negative and positive CEPI is respectively small and large. However, the probability that consumers change their purchase intention in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 89 percent (i.e., probably in the direction predicted) and change their purchase intention in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is 100 percent. Therefore, it can be concluded that in the case of consumer purchase intention toward Hyundai cellular phone, H 3 is confirmed in the case of negative CEPI disclosure and it is strongly confirmed in the case of positive CEPI disclosure. Purchase Intention toward Nongsim Instant Noodle The direction and degree of changes in purchase intention in raw score to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following Figure 6.11. 141 Figure 6.11. Purchase Intention Change toward Nongsim Instant Noodle Purchase Intention Change (Nongsim) —a— Group A —7<— Group B § 7.00 8 6 00 a u E 5 00 é\ § \ O :5” 3.00 3 g 2.00 2 a 1.00 Pre-test Post-test —a— Group A 5.54 5.69 + Group B 5.66 4.00 — Group A was exposed to positive CEPI. - Group B was exposed to negative CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The change in individual purchase intention toward Nongsim instant noodle related to negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -1.67, t (150) = -10.98, p < .001, and CI = -7 to ——1 .41. The extent of change in purchase intention (i.e., effect size) resulting from negative CEPI is very strong: r = -.53, CI = -1 to -.44. The probability that change in purchase intention related to negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: IP = 1.00. However, the gain score in the purchase intention for Nongsim instant noodle related to positive CEPI was significant (in one-tailed significance test at or = 0.05 level): Dw = .15, t (152) = 1.52, p = .066, and CI = -.01 to 7. The effect size ofpurchase intention by positive CEPI is also very small: r = .06, CI = -.07 to 1. The probability that 142 change in purchase intention related to the positive CEPI occurs in the positive direction is not strong: [P = .79. The group mean difference in purchase intention toward Nongsim instant noodle between the two groups that were presented with opposite information is significant: Db= 1.81, t (255) =10.08 and p < .001. Consistent with the case of Samsung, subjects responded to negative CEPI much more strongly (r = -.53) than positive CEPI (r = .06). The data is strongly consistent with H 3 in the case of negative CEPI stimuli but are weakly consistent with H 3 in the case of positive CEPI stimuli. The subjects changed their purchase intention negatively toward Nongsim instant noodle when they were exposed to negative CEPI and changed positively their purchase intention toward Nongsim instant noodle when they were exposed to positive CEPI was statistically significant. The degree of purchase intention change resulting from negative CEPI is very substantial and the probability that consumers would change their purchase intention in the negative direction when they are exposed to the negative CEPI is 100 percent. The degree of change in purchase intention related to the positive CEPI is very weak, however the probability that consumers change their purchase intention in the positive direction when they are exposed to the positive CEPI is still large ([P = .79), meaning that effect occurs probably in the direction predicted. Meanwhile, the result from the two- group comparison revealed that raw mean gain scores of two groups are significantly different. Therefore, it can be concluded that in the case of consumer purchase intention toward Nongsim instant noodle, H 3 is strongly confirmed in the case of negative CEPI disclosure and is also confirmed in the case of positive CEPI disclosure. 143 Purchase Intention toward Binggrae Instant Noodle The direction and extent of change in purchase intention in raw score related to negative and positive CEPI stimuli are presented in the following figure 6.12. Figure 6.12. Purchase intention Change toward Binggrae Instant Noodle Purchase Intention Change (Binggrae) 7.00 6.00 5.00 (A 4.00 \ Purchase Intention (raw score) 3.00 2.00 1.00 ‘ Pre-test Post-test + Group A + Group B +Group A 4.19 3.49 + Group B 4.29 4.82 - Group A was exposed to negative CEPI. - Group B was exposed to positive CEPI. - Data reflect raw scores The change in individual purchase intention toward Binggrae instant noodle related to negative CEPI was significant: Dw = -.70, t (152) = -6.33, p < .001, and CI = - 7 to -.52. The degree of purchase intention change (i.e., effect size) by negative CEPI is moderate: r = -.26, CI = -1 to -. 14. The probability that change in purchase intention related to the negative CEPI occurs in the negative direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. 144 The gain score in the purchase intention for Binggrae instant noodle by positive CEPI was significant: Dw = .53, t (150) = 4.43, p < .001, and CI = .33 to 7. Effect size of purchase intention by positive CEPI was moderate: r = .21, CI = .08 to 1. The probability that changes in purchase intention related to the positive CEPI occur in the positive direction is 100 percent: [P = 1.00. The group mean difference in purchase intention toward Binggrae instant noodle between the two groups that were presented with opposite information is also significant: Db= 1.23, t (302) =7.55 and p < .001. The subjects responded to negative CEPI (r = -.26) and to positive CEPI (r = .21) in the almost equal intensity. The data are strongly consistent with H 3. It was statistically significant that subjects reduced their purchase intention toward Binggrae instant noodle when they were exposed to negative CEPI and increased their purchase intention toward Binggrae instant noodle when they were exposed to positive CEPI. The degree of purchase intention change caused by the both negative and positive CEPI is moderate. The probability that consumers would change their purchase intention in the negative direction when they are exposed to negative CEPI is 100 percent and change their purchase intention in the positive direction when they are exposed to positive CEPI is 100 percent. As a result, it can be concluded that H 3 is strongly confirmed in the case of purchase intention toward Binggrae. Stimuli by Subject Interaction In the absence of error of measurement, any variation in gain scores can be attributed to the Stimuli (i.e., treatment) by Subject Interaction. If there is no Stimuli by 145 Subject Interaction, all individuals have the same change score (i.e., standard deviation of gain score , SD Av = 0). The degree of Stimuli by Subject Interaction can be measured by the followings: 1. Raw score SD “STG” (i.e., Standard deviation of gain score) 2. Standard score SD “5” (STG / Within group SD) 3. Self-impact correlation “ir.” If there are interactions between stimuli and subjects, there would be differences in the effect size that can be explained by different initial level. For example, subjects who have strong attitude toward Samsung may be little sensitive to any information of Samsung, but subject who have weak attitude toward Samsung may strongly response to information about Samsung. This is measured by the extent of the correlation between initial level and effect size. This correlation is called the self-impact correlation (i.e., ir). The sizes of the Stimuli by Subject Interaction related to Attitude, Credibility and Purchase Intention changes are summarized in the following Table 6.23. The Stimuli (i.e., Treatment) by Subject Interaction reported in this Table 6.23 is calculated based on the corrected basic statistics for measurement error. Statistical significance of the Stimuli by Subject Interaction is tested at or = .05 and one-tailed level, assuming that distribution of STG and ir are in a normal curve. 146 Table 6.24 Stimuli by Subject Interaction Attitude Credibility Purchase Intention s STG ir S STG ir s STG ir Samsung A .852 .827 -.287 .815 .661 -.142 .864 1.006 -.528 it it *i it it N Sig it it it Samsung B .994 1.112 -.259 1.015 .917 -.295 .951 1.434 -.186 Hyundai A .831 .958 -.262 .896 .895 -.278 .834 1.038 -.390 Hyundai B 1.046 .978 -.536 .976 .744 -.520 1 .004 1.264 -.389 Nongsim A 1.027 1.001 —.342 1.039 .948 -.350 .988 1.118 -.51 7 Nongsim B 1.251 1.275 -.341 1.185 1.080 -.273 1.366 1.811 -.499 Binggrae A .954 .977 -.188 1.096 1.072 -.282 .985 1.277 -.370 Binggrae B 1.048 .912 -.667 .955 .760 -.564 1.121 1.415 -.686 - s = Standard Score SD (Standard Deviation) - STG = Raw Score SD - it = Self-impact correlation - *"' = Statistically Significant, alpha = .5, two-tailed test - N sig = Not significant Table 6.23 shows that except for a self-impact correlation (ir = -.142) related to credibility change of Samsung Group A, all Stimuli by Subject Interaction of STG, s and ir are statistically significant at or = .05, one-tailed level.'9 It means that masking variables are affecting the extent of the effect of dependent variables: attitude, credibility '9 The fact that standard deviation is not a zero and statistically significant, means that l) masking variables that are unknown variables affecting the intensity of influence of CEPI on attitude, credibility and purchase intention, 2) situational random factors (e.g., hearing a news about Samsung Electronics’ bad behavior just before administration of the post-test), or 3) random fimctioning of human psychology (e.g., participants’ though or feeling during the experiment) were intervened in the experiment. Moderator variable is a special case of masking variable. 147 rl and purchase intention. It also implies that there are moderator variables that influence the effect size of three dependent variables: attitude, credibility and purchase intention. Therefore, it is relevant to investigate moderators for the three dependent variables. Environmental Attitude as a Moderator20 It is hypothesized that a positive relationship exists between consumer environmental attitude toward pollution and consumer purchase behavioral change caused by CEPI disclosure. Thus, the fourth hypothesis (H 4) posited that a customer who has strong environmental attitudes against pollution (EAP) changes the three dependent variables more than a customer who has low EAP. In other words, a positive relationship exists between EAP and the three dependent variables: attitude toward corporation (AC), corporate credibility (CC), and purchase intention (PI). Data analysis results related to H 4 are presented in the following Table 6.24. 2° Moderator is defined as a variable that intervenes between independent and dependent variable and influences the degree of dependent variable. However, it is neither an independent variable nor a mediator variable. Moderator variable is a special case of the masking variable. Masking variables are unknown variables that affect the defendant variable. Meanwhile, Mediator variable is a middle variable located between the first and the final variable in the causal diagram so that mediator is both independent and dependent variable. For more details, see chapter VII, p. 221. 148 Table 6.25 Environmental Attitude toward Pollution and Effect Size of Three Variables Environmental Attitude Credibility Purchase Intention Attitude& r sil IP H4 r sig IP H4 r sig IP H4 Samsung A:+ .09 .126 .88 C -.03 .361 .36 F .04 .312 .69 C Samsung 82- -.26 .001 1.00 C -.33 .000 1.00 C -.34 .000 1.00 C Hyundai A:- -.09 .128 .87 C -.13 .061 .94 C -.24 .002 1.00 C Hyundai B:+ .10 .110 .89 C .04 .310 .69 C .01 .471 .53 F Nongsim A:+ .14 .045 .96 C .13 .054 .95 C .08 .169 .83 C Nongsim B:- -.30 0001.00 C -.21 .006 1.00 C -.20 .006 1.00 C Binggrae A:- -.07 .197 .80 C -.20 .007 .99 C -.20 .007 .99 C Mme B:+ -.01 .467 .47 F .07 .185 .82 C .10 .119 .88 C - A = Group A / B = Group B in the experiment. - Positive CEPI was given to Samsung A, Hyundai B, Nongsim A and Binggrae B - Negative CEPI was given to Samsung B, Hyundai A, Nongsim B and Binggrae A - + / - = Direction of r required to confirm H 4 under CEPI stimuli given - H 4 = positive correlation (+) - "-" is resulted from H 4 ( + ) and negative CEPI (-) - "+" is resulted from H 4 ( + ) and positive CEPI (+) - C = Confirmed / F = need Further research / N = Not confirmed - r = Pearson correlation coefficient - [P = Inference Probability - sig = p-value Environmental Attitude and Attitude toward Corporation Group B’s attitude for Binggrae revealed the opposite directional correlation to H 4: r = -.01, p = .467, and [P = .47. The observed opposite correlation between environmental attitude and attitude about Binggrae is extremely weak (r = -.01) and also not statistically significant (p = .467 at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level). Reverse probability (RP = .53) is almost equivalent to inference probability ([P = .47). Thus, the observed correlation could be considered as “no correlation.” However, inference probability (IP = 149 .47) falls between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ) so the sample size is not large enough to draw a conclusion. For a sound conclusion, we would need further research to decide “no correlation” related to H 4 in the case of positive CEPI stimuli about Binggrae (Group B of Binggrae). Four groups reveal that data are consistent with H 4: Group A of Samsung (r = .09, p = .126, and [P = .88), Group A onyundai (r = -.09, p = .128 and [P = .87), Group B onyundai (r = -.10, p = .110 and [P = .89) and Group A ofBinggrae (r= -.O7, p = .197 and [P = .80). In these four groups, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level, but inference probability is moderately high. It means that the probability that the correlation between environmental attitude and attitude toward corporation is positive (i.e., in the direction hypothesized) is much higher than the reverse probability that the correlation is negative. Therefore, it is concluded that H 4 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Hyundai and Group A of Binggrae. The data from three groups are strongly consistent with H 4: Group B of Samsung (r = -.26, p = .001 and IP = 1.00), Group A of Nongsim (r = .14, p = .045 and [P = .96) and Group B of Nongsim (r = -.30, p < .001 and [P = 1.00). In these three groups, the observed correlations were considerably significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are strongly high. Thus, the researcher concludes that H 4 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group B of Samsung, Group A of Nongsim and Group B of Nongsim. 150 Figure 6.13. Inference Probability of H4 for Attitude toward Corporation Environmental Attitude & Attitude to Corporation '5 In .1: E a .50 o c 2 .2 I: "' '00 A B A B A 8 A 8 Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae [+Series1 .88 1.00 .87 .89 .96 1.00 .80 .47 Figure 6.13 summarizes that except for one case of positive CEPI stimuli about Binggrae (Group B of Binggrae), H 4 is confirmed in all cases (i.e., 7 of 8 cases). For a conclusion concerning Binggrae group B, further research is needed. Thus, the researcher concludes that “environmental attitude toward pollution” is a moderator variable for the variable “attitude toward corporation.” Environmental Attitude and Corporate Credibility Group A’s perception of credibility for Samsung revealed the opposite directional correlation to H 4: r = -.03, p = .361, and [P = .36. For H 4 to be confirmed, the correlation between environmental attitude and credibility of Samsung should be positive because Group A was exposed to positive CEPI of Samsung and hypothesized direction of H 4 is positive. However, the observed correlation is negative (r = -.03). Meanwhile, 151 the observed correlation is not statistically significant (p = .361 at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level). Thus, the observed negative correlation (r = -.03) could be generated from sampling error (Sample size of Group A = 154). Inference probability (IP = .36) falls between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ) so the sample size is not large enough to draw a conclusion. In order to draw a sound conclusion, we would need further research to decide disconfirmation of H 4 in the case of positive CEPI stimuli about Samsung (Group A of Samsung). I The two groups reveal that data are consistent with H 4: Group B of Hyundai (r = -.04, p = .310 and [P = .69) and Group B ofBinggrae (r = -.07, p = .185 and IP = .82). In the two groups, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one- tailed or = 0.05 level. However, the inference probability is larger than .667. This means that the probability that the correlation between environmental attitude and corporate credibility is positive (i.e., in the direction hypothesized) is moderately larger than the reverse probability that the correlation is negative. Therefore, the researcher concludes that H 4 is confirmed in the cases of Group B of Hyundai and Group B of Binggrae. Five groups revealed that data are strongly consistent with H 4: Group B of Samsung (r = -.33, p < .001 and IP = 1.00), Group A onyundai (r = -.13, p = .061 and IP = .94), Group A of Nongsim (r = .13, p = .054 and [P = .95), Group B of Nongsim (r = -.21, p = .006 and IP = 1.00), and Group A of Binggrae (r = -.20, p = .007 and [P = .99). In these five groups, the observed correlations were considerably significant at the one- tailed or = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are strongly high. Thus, this study concludes that H 4 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group B of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group A of Nongsim, Group B of Nongsim, and Group A of Binggrae. 152 Figure 6.14. Inference Probability of H4 for Corporate Credibility Environmental Attitude & Corporate Credibility B I! .0 .9 50 8 / c 2 :3 00 " ' A B A B A 8 A B Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae LSeries1 .36 1.00 .94 .69 .95 1.00 .99 .82 Figure 6.14 shows that except for one case of positive CEPI stimuli about Samsung (Group A of Samsung), H4 is confirmed in all cases (i.e., 7 of 8 cases). For the conclusion about Samsung Group A, further research is needed. Thus, this study concludes that “environmental attitude toward pollution” is a moderator variable for the variable “corporate credibility.” Environme_ntzg Attitude and Purchgse Intention Group B’s purchase intention for Hyundai’s cellular phone revealed “no” correlation: r = .01, p = .471, and [P = .53. The observed correlation between environmental attitude and purchase intention is very weak (r = .01) and also not statistically significant (p = .471 at the one-tailed a = 0.05 level). The inference 153 probability ([P = .53) is almost equivalent to reverse probability (RP = 47). Thus, the observed correlation could be considered as “no correlation.” However inference probability (IP = .53) falls between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ) so the sample size is not large enough to draw a conclusion. Further research is needed to decide “no correlation” in relation to H 4 in the case of positive CEPI stimuli about Hyundai (Group B of Hyundai). Three groups reveal that data are consistent with H 4: Group A of Samsung (r = .04, p = .312, and IP = .69), Group A ofNongsim (r = .08, p = .169 and IP = .83), and Group B of Binggrae (r = .10, p = .119 and [P = .88). In these three groups, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level, but inference probability is moderately high. It means that the probability of a relationship in the hypothesized direction is much higher than the reverse probability of a relationship in the opposite direction of H 4. Therefore, it is concluded that H 4 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group A of Nongsim, and Group B of Binggrae. Four groups revealed that data are strongly consistent with H 4: Group B of Samsung (r = -.34, p < .001 and [P = 1.00), Group A of Hyundai (r = -.24, p = .002 and [P = 1.00), Group B of Nongsim (r = -.20, p = .006 and [P = 1.00) and Group A of Binggrae (r = -.20, p = .007 and IP = .99). In these four groups, the observed correlations were considerably significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are very high. Thus, it is concluded that H 4 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group B of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae. 154 Figure 6.15. Inference Probability of H4 for Purchase Intention Environmental Attitude & Purchase Intention E u .D 2 n. .50 o o c 2 :3 00 " ' A B A B A 8 A B Sansung Sansung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae Series1 .69 1.00 1.00 .53 .83 1.00 .99 .88 Figure 6.15 shows that except for one case of positive CEPI stimuli about Hyundai (Group B of Hyundai), H 4 is confirmed in all of the cases (i.e., 7 of 8 cases). For a conclusion concerning the Hyundai group B, further research is needed. Thus, it is concluded that “environmental attitude toward pollution” is a moderator variable for the variable “purchase intention.” Corporate Familiarity as a Moderator Hypothesis Five (H 5) posited that consumers with high familiarity with a corporation (CFC) change their consumer attitude (AC), corporate credibility (CC), and purchase intention (PI) less than one with low familiarity. In order words, H 5 states that a negative relationship exists between CFC and three variables of AC, CC, and PI. Data analysis results related to H 5 is presented in the following table 6.25. 155 Table 6.26 Familiarity with Corporation and Effect Size of Three Variables Familiarity & Attitude Credibility Purchase Intention r siLlP H5 r sig IP H5 r sig—IP H5 Samsung A:- -.15 .029 .97 C -.10 .108 .90 C -.22 .003 1.00 C Samsung B:+ -.20 .008 .01 N -.12 .071 .07 N -.07 .210 .21 N Hyundai A:+ .07 .193 .81 C .01 .439 .56 F .08 .177 .82 C Hyundai 82- .00 .482 .48 F -.08 .153 .85 C -.01 .448 .55 F Nongsim A:- -.19 .010 .99 C -.07 .199 .80 C -.17 .017 .99 C Nongsim B:+ -.05 .279 .28 N .00 .494 .50 F -.01 .453 .45 F Binggrae A:+ -.04 .301 .30 N .01 .431 .57 F -.05 .288 .29 N Mme B:- -.28 0001.00 C -.22 .003 1.00 C -.24 .001 1.00 C - A = Group A / B = Group B in the experiment. - Positive CEPI was given to Samsung A, Hyundai B, Nongsim A and Binggrae B - Negative CEPI was given to Samsung B, Hyundai A, Nongsim B and Binggrae A - + / - = Direction of r required to confirm H 5 under CEPI stimuli given - H 5: negative correlation (-) - "+" is resulted from H 5 ( - ) and negative CEPI (-) - "-" is resulted from H 5 ( - ) and positive CEPI (+) - C = Confirmed / F = need Further research / N = Not confirmed - r = Pearson correlation coefficient - IP = Inference Probability - sig = p—value Familiarity fll Attitude toward Corporation Three groups’ attitudes revealed the considerably opposite directional correlation to H 5: Group B of Samsung (r = -.20, p = .008, and IP = .01), Group B of Nongsim (r = - .05, p = 279 and [P = .28) and Group A of Binggrae (r = -.04, p = .301 and IP = .30). In all three cases, the observed correlation should be positive in order to confirm H 5 because negative CEPI was given to them. However, the directions of observed correlation are negative and the correlations are statistically significant at the one—tailed or 156 = 0.05 level. Reverse probabilities are considerably higher than the inference probability: Group B of Samsung (RP = .99), Group B of Nongsim (RP = .72) and Group A of Binggrae (RP = .70). It means that the probability of response occurring in the opposite direction of H 5 is significantly larger than the probability of its occurring in the same direction of H 5. Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 is strongly disconfirmed in the case of Group B of Samsung, Group B of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae. Data revealed that no correlations would exist between familiarity and attitude in one case: Group B of Hyundai (r = -.00, p = .482 and IP = .48). For Group B of Hyundai, the observed correlations were zero and not statistically significant at one-tailed or = 0.05 level. [P (.48) is almost equivalent to RP (1- .48 = .52). Meanwhile, the inference probability (IP = .48) falls between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ) and the sample size is not large enough to draw a conclusion. Further research is needed to conclude that “no correlation” is related to H 5 in the cases of Group B of Hyundai. A group revealed that data are consistent with H 5: Group A of Hyundai (r = .07, p = .193 and [P = .81). In this group, the observed correlation should be positive in order to confirm H 5 because negative CEPI was given to them. The result correlation observed was positive. The observed correlations were not significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level, but the inference probabilities was moderately higher than RP (1 - .81 = .19). Thus, it is concluded that H 5 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Hyundai. Three cases showed that data are strongly consistent with H 5: Group A of Samsung (r = -.15, p = .029 and IP = .97), Group A ofNongsim (r = -.19, p = .010 and [P = .99) and Group B of Binggrae (r = -.28, p < .001 and IP = 1.00). In these three cases, the observed correlations are significant and the inference probabilities are very high. 157 Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group A of Nongsim and Group B of Binggrae. Figure 6.16. Inference Probability of H5 for Attitude toward Corporation Familiarity and Attitude 1.00 '3 «II .n E 50 3 U I: 2 2 E '00 A 8 A B A 8 Samsung Samsung AHyundaI B HyundaI Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae Series1 .97 .01 .81 .48 .99 .28 .30 1.00 Figure 6.16 shows that familiarity with corporations is a severe contingency2| variable for attitude toward corporation, related to the CEPI disclosure. H 5 is confirmed in the four cases, but disconfirrned for the three cases. For the conclusion of one case, additional research is needed. Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 related to attitude toward corporation is disconfinned and “familiarity” is not a moderator variable to the variable “attitude toward corporation.” 2' Contingency variable is defined as a variable, of which effect occurs in both positive and negative direction. Contingency variable is a special case of the moderator variable. 158 Familiarity and Comorgte Credibility Group B’s perception of credibility for Samsung revealed the strongly opposite directional correlation to H 5: r = -.12, p = .071, and [P = .07. For H 5 to be confirmed, the correlation between familiarity and credibility for Samsung should be positive because Group B was exposed to negative CEPI of Samsung and the hypothesized direction of H S is negative. However, the observed correlation is negative (r = -.12) and is statistically significant (p = .071 at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level). The inference probability is .07 and the reverse probability (RP)22 is .93 (i.e., RP = 1-.07 = .93). The probability that the correlation between familiarity and corporate credibility exists in the opposite direction of H 5 is very larger than the probability that the correlation exists in the same direction of H 5. Therefore, it is concluded that H 5 is strongly disconfirmed in the case of negative CEPI stimuli about Samsung (Group B of Samsung). Data revealed that there “no correlation” or “almost no correlations” would exist between familiarity and attitude in the three cases: Group A of Hyundai (r = -.01, p = .439 and IP = .56), Group B of Nongsim (r = .00, p = .494 and [P = .50) and Group A of Binggrae (r = .01, p = .431 and IP = .57). For Group B of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at one-tailed 0I = 0.05 level and IP was almost equivalent to RP. It means that the probability of the correlation existing in the hypothesized direction is almost equal to the reverse probability of its correlation existing in the opposite direction of H 5. However, the inference probabilities fall between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ); thus, the sample 22 Reverse probability (RP) is the probability that effect occurs in the opposite direction of hypothesis. 159 size is not large enough to make conclusions. To draw a conclusion, we need further research to decide that “no correlation” exists in relation to H 5 in the cases of Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae. The three groups revealed that data are moderately consistent with H 5: Group A of Samsung (r = -.10, p = .108 and [P = .90), Group B onyundai (r = -.08, p = .153 and [P = .85) and Group A of Nongsim (r = -.07, p = .199 and [P = .80). In these three groups, the observed correlations were not significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level but the inference probabilities are substantially higher than RP. Thus, this study concludes that H 5 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group B of Hyundai and Group A of Nongsim. One case showed that the data are strongly consistent with H 5: Group B of Binggrae (r = -.22, p = .003 and [P = 1.00. In this case, the correlation is significant and the probability that the correlation between familiarity and corporate credibility exists in the direction opposite to H 5 is .00 (RP =1- 1.00). Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group B of Binggrae. 160 Figure 6.17. Inference Probability of H5 for Corporate Credibility Familiarity and Corporate Credibility 1. :E' 00 3 III n i 60 \ 3 . r: 2 .2 E .00 A B A B A B A 8 Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae Series1 .90 .07 .56 .85 .80 .50 .57 1.00 Figure 6.17 shows that familiarity with a corporation is a severe contingency23 variable for corporate credibility, related to the CEPI disclosure. H 5 is confirmed in the four cases, but disconfirmed in the case of Group B of Samsung. Further research is needed to conclude that no correlation exists in the three cases. Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 related to corporate credibility is disconfirmed and “familiarity” is not a moderator variable to the variable “corporate credibility.” Familigrity and Purchase Intention Two groups’ perception of credibility revealed a considerably opposite directional correlation to H 5: Group B of Samsung (r = -.O7, p = .210, and [P = .21) and Group A of Binggrae (r = -.05, p = .288 and [P = .29). In these two cases, the observed correlations are not statistically significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level but reverse probabilities are 23 Contingency variable is defined as a variable, of which effect occurs in both positive and negative direction. Contingency variable is a special case of the moderator variable. 161 higher than inference probability: Group B of Samsung (RP = .79) and Group A of Binggrae (RP = .71). It means that the probability that the correlation between corporate familiarity and purchase intention exists in the opposite direction of H 5 is significantly stronger than the probability that the correlation exists in the same direction of H 5. Therefore, this study concludes that H 5 is strongly disconfirmed in the case of Group B of Samsung and Group A of Binggrae. Data revealed that almost no correlations exists between familiarity and attitude in the two cases: Group B onyundai (r = -.01, p = .448 and [P = .55) and Group B of Nongsim (r = -.01, p = .453 and [P = .45). In these two cases, the observed correlations are almost zero and not statistically significant at one-tailed or = 0.05 level. [P is almost equivalent to RP: Group B of Hyundai (RP = .45) and Group B of Nongsim (RP = .55). However, the inference probabilities fall between .333 and .667 ( 1/3 < [P < 2/3 ) with the result that the sample size is not large enough to draw a conclusion. As a conclusion, further research is needed to decide “no correlation” related to H 5 in the cases of Group B of Hyundai and Group B of Nongsim. One group revealed that data are consistent with H 5: Group A of Hyundai (r = - .08, p = .177 and [P = .82). In this group, the observed correlations were not significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level but the inference probabilities are moderately higher than RP (1 - .81 = .19). Thus, it is concluded that H 5 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Hyundai. Three cases showed that data are strongly consistent with H 5: Group A of Samsung (r = -.22, p = .003 and [P = 1.00), Group A of Nongsim (r = -.17, p = .017 and [P = .99) and Group B of Binggrae (r = -.24, p = .001 and IP = 1.00). In these three cases, 162 the observed correlations are significant and the inference probabilities are very high. Therefore, it is concluded that H 5 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group A of Nongsim and Group B of Binggrae. Figure 6.18. Inference Probability of H5 for Purchase Intention Familiarity and Purchase Intention :- 1.00 3 III .9 2 50 3 i V c 2 8 - .00 A B A 8 A 8 A 8 Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae [Siries1 1.00 .21 .82 .55 .99 .45 .29 1.00 Figure 6.18 shows that familiarity with corporations is a severe contingency variable for purchase intention, related to the CEPI disclosure. H 5 is confirmed in the four cases, but for the two cases H 5 is disconfirmed. For the conclusion in the two cases, further research is needed. Thus, this study concludes that H 5 related to purchase intention is disconfirmed and “familiarity” is not a moderator variable to the variable “purchase intention.” Information Credibility as a Moderator Hypothesis Six (H 6) posited that the greater the credibility of CEPI (CCI), the greater the effect of the CEPI rating on the three dependent variables: consumer attitude 163 (AC), corporate credibility (CC), and purchase intention (PI). That is, a positive relationship exists between CCI and the three dependent variables: AC, CC, and PI. Data analysis results related to H 6 are presented in the following Table 6.26. Table 6.27 Information Credibility and Effect Size of Three Variables Information Attitude Credibility Purchase Intention Credibility& r sig IP H6 r sig lP H6 r sig IP H6 Samsung A:+ .21 0051.00 C .28 .000 1.00 C .25 .001 1.00 C Samsung 82- -.21 0041.00 C -.11 .094 .91 C -.11 .093 .91 C Hyundai A:- -.24 .001 1.00 C -.31 .000 1.00 C -.14 .041 .96 C Hyundai B:+ .11 .088 .92 C .16 .027 .98 C .14 .046 .96 C Nongsim A:+ .15 .037 .97 C .18 .014 .99 C .07 .184 .82 C Nongsim B:- -.09 .148 .85 C -.06 .239 .76 C -.21 .005 1.00 C Binggrae A:.- -.26 .001 1.00 C -.27 .000 1.00 C -.05 .284 .72 C Binggrae B:+ .27 0001.00 C .24 .001 1.00 C .12 .066 .94 C - A = Group A / B = Group B in the experiment. - Positive CEPI was given to Samsung A, Hyundai B, Nongsim A and Binggrae B - Negative CEPI was given to Samsung B, Hyundai A, Nongsim B and Binggrae A - + / - = Direction of r required to confirm H 6 under CEPI stimuli given - H 6: positive correlation (+) - "-" is resulted from H 6 ( + ) and negative CEPI (—) - "+" is resulted from H 6 ( + ) and positive CEPI (+) - C = Confirmed / F = need Further research / N = Not confirmed - r = Pearson correlation coefficient - IP = Inference Probability - sig = p-value Information Credibility and Attitude toward Corporation Related to attitude change, Group B of Nongsim revealed that data are consistent with H 6: r = -.09, p = .148, and [P = .85. In this case, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one-tailed a = 0.05 level, but inference probability is larger 164 than RP (1 - .85 = .15). It means that the probability that the correlation between CEPI credibility and attitude toward corporation is positive (i.e., the hypothesized direction of H 6) is considerably larger than the reverse probability that the correlation is negative. Therefore, it is concluded that H 6 is confirmed in the cases of Group B of Nongsim. Except for Group B of Nongsim, seven of eight groups revealed that data are strongly consistent of H 6: Group A of Samsung (r = .21, p = .005 and [P = 1.00), Group B of Samsung (r = -.21, p = .004 and IP = 1.00), Group A of Hyundai (r = -.24, p = .001 and [P = 1.00), Group B of Hyundai (r = .11, p = .088 and [P = .92), Group A of Nongsim (r = .15, p = .037 and [P = .97), Group A of Binggrae (r = -.26, p = .001 and [P = 1.00), and Group B of Binggrae (r = .27, p < .001 and IP = 1.00). In these seven groups, the observed correlations were highly significant at the one-tailed 01 = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are very high. Thus, this study concludes that H 6 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group B of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Hyundai, Group A of Nongsim, Group A of Binggrae and Group B of Binggrae. 165 Figure 6.19. Inference Probability of H 6 for Attitude toward Corporation Information Credibility 8. Attitude g 1-00 C t W ¢ 23 a .0 E w .50 o c 2 a E .00 A B A B A B A 8 Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae Eerie“ 1.00 1.00 1.00 .92 .97 .85 1.00 1.00 Figure 6.19 shows that data are strongly consistent with H 6 in 7 of 8 cases and consistent with H 6 in one case. Therefore, this study concludes that H 6 about attitude toward corporation is confirmed and “information credibility” is a moderator variable to the variable “attitude toward corporation.” Information Credibility and Corporate Credibility Group B of Nongsim related to credibility change revealed that the data is consistent with H 6: r = -.06, p = .239, and [P = .76. In this case, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one-tailed CI = 0.05 level, but the inference probability is larger than the reverse probability (RP: l - .76 = .24). It means that the probability of positive correlation between CEPI credibility and corporate credibility is considerably larger than the probability that the correlation is negative (i.e., 166 the opposite direction of H 6). Therefore, it is concluded that H 6 is confirmed in the cases of Group B of Nongsim. Except for Group B of Nongsim, the seven of eight groups revealed that data are strongly consistent with H 6: Group A of Samsung (r = .28, p < .001 and IP = 1.00), Group B of Samsung (r = -.11, p = .094 and IP = .91), Group A onyundai (r = -.31, p < .001 and [P = 1.00), Group B of Hyundai (r = .16, p = .027 and [P = .98), Group A of Nongsim (r = .18, p = .014 and [P = .99), Group A of Binggrae (r = -.27, p < .001 and [P = 1.00), and Group B of Binggrae (r = .24, p = .001 and [P = 1.00). In these seven groups, the observed correlations were considerably significant at the one-tailed or = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are strongly high. Thus, this study concludes that H 6 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group B of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Hyundai, Group A of Nongsim, Group A of Binggrae and Group B of Binggrae. Figure 6.20. Inference Probability of H6 for Corporate Credibility Information Credibility & Corporate Credbility E 1.00 W 4 3 «I a 2 n. a .50 u I: 2 .9 I: " '00 A B A B A B A 8 Samsung Samsung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae [Series1 1.00 .91 1.00 .98 .99 .76 1.00 1.00 167 Figure 6.20 shows that data are strongly consistent with H 6 in 7 of 8 cases and consistent with H 6 in one case. Therefore, this study concludes that H 6 related to corporate credibility is confirmed and “information credibility” is a moderator variable to the variable “corporate credibility.” Information Credibility and Purchase Intention Related to purchase intention, data about two groups are consistent with H 6: Group A of Nongsim (r = .07, p = .184, and IP = .82) and Group A of Binggrae (r = -.05, p = .284 and IP = .72). In these two cases, the observed correlations were not statistically significant at the one-tailed 0: = 0.05 level, but inference probability is larger than RP: Group A of Nongsim (RP = 1 - .82 = .18) and Group A of Binggrae (RP = 1 - .72 = .28). It means that the probabilities that the correlation between CEPI credibility and purchase intention exists in the hypothesized direction are considerably larger than the reverse probabilities that the correlation exists in the opposite direction of H 6. Therefore, it is concluded that H 6 is confirmed in the cases of Group A of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae. Except for the Group A of Nongsim and Group A of Binggrae, six of eight groups revealed that data are strongly consistent with H 6: Group A of Samsung (r = .25, p = .001 and IP = 1.00), Group B of Samsung (r = -.11, p = .093 and IP = .91), Group A of Hyundai (r = -.14, p = .041 and IP = .96), Group B onyundai (r = .14, p = .046 and [P = .96), Group B of Nongsim (r = -.21, p = .005 and IP = 1.00) and Group B of Binggrae (r 168 = .12, p = .066 and IP = .94). In these six groups, the observed correlations were strongly significant at the one-tailed a = 0.05 level and the inference probabilities are very high. Thus, this study concludes that H 6 is strongly confirmed in the cases of Group A of Samsung, Group B of Samsung, Group A of Hyundai, Group B of Hyundai, Group B of Nongsim and Group B of Binggrae. Figure 6.21. Inference Probability of H 6 for Purchase Intention Information Credibility & Purchase Intention 3. 1.00 A g Vv—VV a .n 2 n- .50 o u c o 3 I.- 5 .00 A B A B A B A B Sarrsung Sansung Hyundai Hyundai Nongsim Nongsim Binggrae Binggrae [Series1 1.00 .91 .96 .96 .82 1.00 .72 .94 Figure 6.21 shows that data are strongly consistent with H 6 in 6 of 8 cases and also consist of H 6 in 2 cases. Therefore, the researcher concludes that H 6 related to purchase intention is disconfirmed and “information credibility” is a moderator variable to the variable “purchase intention.” 169 CHAPTER VII DISCUSSION AND INTERPRETATION Chapter VI reported statistical data analysis and results. Results include both effects of the corporate environmental performance information (CEPI) about the four Korean corporations (i.e., Samsung, Hyundai, Nongsim and Binggrae) and effects of three moderators (i.e., familiarity with corporations, environmental attitude and CEPI credibility) on three dependent variables (i.e., attitude toward the four corporation, credibility of the four corporation and purchase intention toward the products of the four corporations). This study’s experiment tests the six hypotheses regarding PID. Among them, five hypotheses (H 1, 2, 3, 4, and 6) were confirmed, and one hypothesis (H 5) was disconfirmed. Participants in this experimental test consisted of three hundred and six Korean university students. The amount of results reported in the last chapter is vast, and its contents are complex. In order to obtain more clear understandings about the test results and to conduct rich discussion and appropriate interpretations for the test results, it is needed to organize the results of data analysis in the way of comparing all results from the four corporations. Thus, this chapter begins with summary and comparison of the results of all hypotheses tests. Summary of Test of Hypothesis One, Two and Three As shown in Table 7.1, all three major hypotheses are confirmed. The three hypotheses are as follows: 170 H 1: CEPI disclosures change consumer attitude toward corporations positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. H 2: CEPI disclosures change the consumers’ perception of corporate credibility positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. H 3: CEPI disclosures increase consumer purchase intention for the products of non-polluting corporations and decrease consumer purchase intention for the products of polluting corporations. Table 7.1 Summary of Test of Hypothesis One, Two and Three Samsung Hyundai Nongsim Binggrae H l: Attitude N.CEPI S. Confirmed 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed S. Confirmed P. CEPI 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed Confirmed S. Confirmed H2: Credibility N. CEPI 8. Confirmed S. Confirmed S. Confirmed S. Confirmed P. CEPI 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed S. Confirmed S. Confirmed H3: Purchase N. CEPI 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed 8. Confirmed Intention P. CEPI 8. Confirmed S. Confirmed Confirmed S. Confirmed - S. Confirmed = Strongly Confirmed - N. CEPI = Negative CEPI - P. CEPI = Positive CEPI Table 7.1 shows that all of the Hypothesis One, Two and Three are confirmed. In the case of attitude change of Nongsim by positive CEPI, stimuli correlation is very weak 171 (r = .06) and credibility change is barely significant (p = .100) at the level of a = .05 and one-tailed significance test. However, inference probability is larger (IP = .76) than reverse probability (R1 = .24). Thus, attitude change of Nongsim is interpreted as probably in the direction hypothesized. In the case of purchase intention toward Nongsim instant noodle by positive CEPI, stimuli correlation is very small (r = .06). However, purchase intention change is significant (p = .066) at the level of or = .05 and one-tailed significance test and inference probability is larger (IP = .79) than reverse probability (R1 = .21). Thus, the purchase intention change toward Nongsim instant noodle is interpreted as probably in the direction hypothesized. Except these two cases, all cases retained strong stimuli correlations, highly significant change of gain scores and high inference probability. In the following, results of data analysis about changes of attitude, credibility, and purchase intention caused by CEPI disclosure are summarized in the charts. CEPI Disclosure and Change of Attitude toward Corporflm: H 1 The Hypothesis One (H 1) is that CEPI disclosures change consumer attitude toward corporations (AC) positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporation. 172 Figure 7.1. Attitude Change and Effect Direction D of Attitude 3.00 2.00 1.00 .00 “ -1.00 ‘ -2.00 -3.00 Raw Gain Score 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 ISeries1 .24 -1.03 .59 -.55 .11 -1.50 .61 -.73 - D = Mean of difference of raw score between time 1 (Pre-test) and time 2 (Post-test). - Raw score scale is —7 to 7. - 1 = the case of Positive CEPI of Samsung 2 = the case of Negative CEPI of Samsung 3 = the case of Positive CEPI of Hyundai 4 = the case of Negative CEPI of Hyundai 5 = the case of Positive CEPI of Nongsim 6 = the case of Negative CEPI of Nongsim 7 = the case of Positive CEPI of Binggrae 8 = the case of Negative CEPI of Binggrae - These notes also apply to the next Figure 7.2, 7.3, 7.4, 7.5, 7.6, 7.7, 7.8 and 7.9. Figure 7.1 summarizes the result that the subjects changed their level of attitude of the four corporations in the negative direction when they were exposed to negative CEPI of the four corporations, and that the subjects changed their attitude toward the four corporations in the positive direction when they were exposed to positive CEPI of the four corporations. 173 Figure 7.2 Stimuli Correlation of Attitude Change as Effect Size and Pattern Effect Size (Attitude Change) 1.00 .80 .60 .40 .20 .00 -.20 -.40 —.60 -.80 -1.00 Stimuli r 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 ISeries1 .12 -.42 .30 -.23 .06 -.59 .33 -.34 Figure 7.2 shows that the extent of attitude changes in response to CEPI (stimuli effect size) varies depending on corporations and on the positive or negative of CEPI. No pattern by corporation was found in attitude changes. However, subjects responded more sensitively to negative information than to positive information about Samsung and Nongsim. For Hyundai, subjects more sensitively responded to positive information than negative information. 174 Figure 7.3. Probability of Effect in the Direction Predicted (Inference Probability) Inference Probability Effect Direction (Attitude Change) .50 .00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 +Series1 .94 1.00 1.00 1.00 .76 1.00 1.00 1.00 Figure7.3 reveals two findings: 1. The probabilities that the population (i.e., the Korean university students) of subjects changes their attitude toward the four corporations in the negative direction are very high (100 %) for all cases when they are exposed to negative CEPI. The probabilities that the population changes their attitude of the four corporations in the positive direction are very high (100 %) for three cases, high (76 %) for one case and moderate (76 %) for one case when they are exposed to positive CEPI. 175 No pattern by negative and positive CEPI was found in attitude changes. However, subjects’ showed a more discemable response to negative information than to positive information. CEPI Disclosure and Chage of Corporate Credibility: H 2 The Hypothesis Two (H 2) is that CEPI disclosures change consumers’ perception of corporate credibility (CC) positively for non-polluting corporations and negatively for polluting corporations. Figure 7.4. Corporate Credibility Change and Effect Direction D of Credibility 3.00 2 2.00 3 100 a, . = - J -- .oo~ 8 I I I .— 5 -1.00 -2.00 -3.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 .Series1 .38 -.81 .62 -.57 .28 -1.21 .55 -.67 Figure 7.4 summarizes the result that subjects changed their perception of credibility for four corporations to the negative direction when they were exposed to negative CEPI of the four corporations, and subjects changed their perception of 176 credibility for four corporations in the positive direction when they were exposed to positive CEPI of the four corporations. Figure 7.5. Stimuli Correlation of Credibility Change as Effect Size and Pattern Effect Size (Credibility Change) 1.00 .80 .60 .40 .20 .00 -.20 -.40 -.60 -.80 -1.00 Stimuli r fl Series1 Figure 7.2 shows that the extent of credibility changes in response to CEPI (stimuli effect size) varies depending on the corporations and on the positive or negative of CEPI. No pattern by corporation was found in credibility changes. However, subjects responded more sensitively to negative information than to positive information about Samsung and Nongsim. For Hyundai, subjects more sensitively responded to positive information than to negative information. This tendency of sensitivity by corporation related to credibility change is consistent with the tendency of sensitivity related to attitude change. 177 Figure7.6. Probability of Effect in the Direction Predicted (Inference Probability) Inference Probability Effect Direction (Credibility Change) 1.oo——o—o-—o—+ For a predicted positive correlation, the inference probability is the probability of rho being positive, i.e., P(p > 0). Asking the value of the inference probability is a very useful question to ask, for if you hypothesized and expected a positive correlation, then the estimate of the inference probability gives you an idea of how probable your research hypothesis is. For example, suppose that IP was .79. That means that it is very likely that rho is positive, the chance of your directional hypothesis coming true is estimated to be about 79%. In fancy mathematical notion, the inference probability is P=Pm0 Reverse probability. The reverse probability is the probability that the directional hypothesis is incorrect, i.e., that the population correlation, rho, is not positive. The reverse probability is defined as RP=1-IP Figure 7-3 How is the IP calculated? You may be awed by the fancy definition of the inference probability. However, from a practical point of view, calculating the [P is a cup of tea and a piece of cake. At this point I am assuming that you really know how to get areas under the normal curve. If it is a bit fuzzy and you do not feel as confident about calculating areas, go back to the homework . problems in Chapter 2 (associated with my notes) Sample correlat'on’ or Shavelson’s Chapter 5 to see how to do those 69-. r xy = -45 calculations. 0.0 .4 2 Appendix D. is directly quoted from an unpublished paper (i.e., notes of course Psychology 815) of Dr. Ralph Levine who was a professor in the Department of Psychology and is a professor in the Department of Resource Development at Michigan State University. The researcher appreciates his allowance for quoting parts of his unpublished manuscript. 265 The inference probability is the probability that rho is positive, if your directional hypothesis is positive or the inference probability is the probability that rho is negative when positing a negative value of rho. From the point of view of areas under the curve, most of the time the IP will be at least .50. To see this, look at the Figure (7-3) Suppose your sample correlation were .45. In the figure you can see that .45 is placed in the center of the normal distribution. We are looking for the probability of being positive. The positive values start from a correlation of 0.0 and then go to the end of the curve which would be a correlation of 1.0. The areas under the curve are the probabilities. These areas are B, which extends from the .45 to 1.0 and A which goes from r = .00 to r = .45. Area A is 50% of the distribution. All we need to calculate is the f area under the curve from 0.0 to the sample correlation, which in this sample is .45. I In order to use the Standard normal curve table in the back of Shavelson or to convert the raw correlation .45 to a z score, we need two things, namely the mean (which is .45) and a standard deviation. The stande deviation is estimated by using a formula like Equation which is the formula for the standard error of the correlation coefficient. Once the mean and the standard error are known, we can find the z score for a correlation is of 0.0 and use the standard normal table to find the probability of area A. Then all we have to do is to add the probabilities of areas A and B together to obtain an estimate of the inference probability. Concretely, for the case where we predict a positive correlation do the following steps: 1. Place the normal curve around your sample correlation by letting your sample correlation be the mean of the distribution. 2. Calculate the standard error 3. Calculate the z score that corresponds to a correlation of 0.0 4. Find the area under the curve from the z score found in step 3. This Area A 5. Since the sample correlation is in the center of the distribution all you have to do is add .50, the probability of falling in Area B, to the probability of falling in Area A. That sum is the IP! [Interpretation of the IP when the sample correlation is 0.0. If the sample correlation is exactly 0.0, then Area B equals .50, and Area A = 0.0. The [P in this case would be exactly 50%.] 266 a Mom :23 LL are as saw are H a EOIXI. *léloll Lila 0:131 h .9. c1 ( q as Jr Appendix E Korean Version of QUESTIONNAIRE FOR THE EXPERIMENTAL TEST gill} £22194 5453 OIEHOII J(“MEI El§0l| %3 I: 11" 2 7|9=1§OII Elli-ii Ciel allilli E3H -’i‘-1‘=M|Si. Oii‘iE-P-I ’EUZIOI 2 O 2. ennui Ir—aasm 3114191 area via-Alas] tile eels—24 slalom :21 5| 9.125 %ZIE’J 4 3.1% 9151MB Ell-4111. —% ‘O'E TF5ll-’i‘-’él’\lS’.? >:< 01213.3 83111ng 7:101 avg/~12. 1. aeaxl aaaafl $142} 3 Pre—Test Questionnaire HENRI %E—J EIAIOI Cl >265) .xrozfl SEEN WEN. €an are .flfl arm 267 2 1 flilfilll as elxloltl ¢H|Xl§ 5.33561:— §|Al7l OILICI 3. %49 749131419} 3363?} El%*l%l°ll Ellis} 043151-91 43210114 £74123- ‘o’E 3H 3643 419.? %Hilkifll Ec'.=’.‘=l§|/ll.‘ll aaae EHEE Cilfiili HEQOIEI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Ellilli JE’EOIEI 113153 £61218 Q Bill %Elfil 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q F‘JECI NEIBIXI %E Halal EIEI §|AIOIEI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 §IAIOICI fittlleE Eéfil-t- _ fitHIXIS Eéfil-E 5WD) olLICI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 §|A)0|L'.l- 4. ‘fl—‘lifil 3193314191 133% Pl%*l§l°ll EH3} alibi-94 4321014 521%‘0’3 311 2923134194 gnalalxlgl aaae aaae Eiliili XiEEOIf—I 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 EIIXIIE JEEOIEI 7431553 @8158 E Bill %Eltl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 it PJECI L'ElaiXI %E L'EI‘ are §|A10|tl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 §|A)0|L'.l 553mg EEGIE .’tfllxli ééfil-t- amp) 0114:) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 4| IOIEI 5.4149411} $565M ilxloil 3172151419 ANION 1:29—8- 0131221111771 Eatol LIED} 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 glam gt} HEIE 4‘— SJICI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Hill: 4‘- 916i egaoltl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 agaioltl gmyq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 gmgq 6.2353411} 1.1413317] 31401 £16.} 64121 421014 1:64:— ole-slam} germ Lien 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 gatol if-Cl- flilg 4‘- ‘RJICI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 {ERIE 4‘- 916i %EHMH 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 ggamq NNEH 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 imam 268 7. s41 alt-1:144] £118.} 34121 4171014 e744:— 0161—3141144? glam 14311:) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 galol Zg-tl NEH-El -1‘- 91121 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Nil? 4‘- $21121 EEEMG 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 ggfimq NNEG 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 §m§q 8. "9:13! alflillloll Ella} 5314191 8210M 126-8- 011113141147}? glam 149.411 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 galol gt) Nile-ii -’t— 21121 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 {LEIQ 4‘- 2,1111 $§§10|Cl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 2513mm amen 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 gmgq >-'< 11% 7|fi§0| $1.1 E§l7|91 @315 {NIEE Aléloll EL éMElF—l. 0|? {Hill fig :r‘DH‘éi 7132111 944171 211-Ell. :1 ESE OIEIIOII IIIME' EQOII 133315” E 51 %Sél/KIE. Dial-“.1194 éUZlOI EE- 5—6 aom 135.3 53% EPJXI aW313“ 9:125 $7.191 4 11% 511614134 ELICI. 1. 421% 51141751317] 4111%--%... EEGIJQXI 9.11:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 Q 512.1313 3:161 4°45le 911% 31 Lilli 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 #1212 Ed @111 31%| 7l-EQOI 91111 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 519:1 7i-‘5—SOI 91111 2. i{lull Eli/$141317] fill-16%... 3119:1611 gm alt) 1 2 3 4 5 6 #946170 9.1% at £61 1 2 3 4 5 6 $21 7i-‘5—élol 91111 1 2 Q “7‘21 3111 41 Cl Q $942 3d 251 419:1 7i-S-éiol 531111 (.0 as U" 03 Q 269 3. e41 113}?! 4.111%-%... $0.46): gm 91:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 {19:16}: 441:) :ii‘iélflxl 9.13 at £51 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 43151243161 7112-] 713210! 91121 1 2 w 4s 01 0‘ Q 421 71549 0| 94151 4. 49:11:] 6691.14165- a... $94611 4,126 9.11:} 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 4.216111 411:} $9461?“ 31% ad EDI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 FEE ad ZJEI 'TL‘EJ NESOI 9117—1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 $194 7i'S-éJOI $3151 >I< Elg- EEO" EIISII Ciel-ti- 412121 %JflfiiE 3&0" ’O'E SHEFQAIE. 1. LIE- :15} Elli-616.1% Bl 61311611 “431414111 564111617] 5141” 0" lill6Il... Q E_ Biol %‘1 2.1%: Eloltl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 $2.15 EIOIEI 2. Ll°ll4fl “4134111 %flflilflili‘Pfl @1183 EDIE) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 (Ala-El EDIE) 3. LI: 636.6 61613-361 61616141 “EEIIEZI 5141 4167M 3141““ Ell6ll... 6* EE-t- 9101 an 216:— EDIE) 1 2 3 4 5 7 21‘5- EDIE) O) 4. 616117.11 “fitllflZl—‘i— «(16171514 7}“ it EE-t— E'JOI 21:1 ‘21-:- EDIE) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 91E rEIOIEI 270 6. #011411 “36649 31915149) films; EDIE) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 916663 EOICI 7. U165 33%} 611511436511 11131161141 ”91%| al‘flfil‘l’fll Cll6ll... Q EE-t— BIOI call 21% EOIEI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 215 EDIE.) >:< :3 E210" 1:161 0161-5- 412121 %JilfilE 51-011 '65 616—41412. 1945171 9.03% 66171 $1611, 61—3— 7166:- 61414 61.4.6.- 6121 94:11, 714161 7.461 1:111 411:1." L11:- 61°11... (1)5612: 1111111 (211111111 (313711364121 (4)849 (5161612; 6.161 3 ----- 4 ----- 5 II??- Ell E-E EOIEi 3. “.6173 65553— 191-5161:? %%€— 661-616 9.1561." LIE 61611... (1161669.: ELIEH (2)3161 (313711215161 (416.164 (5)5612: £161 “216% E11161-65: E61156?! 3341—1:- iLE’JEEE—El 113.61% $20101 6.1131.” LIE 0] (DEEP—E ELHIH (2)91511 (3)3113Es‘cl (4)5321 ($515123 HQ 5. 1361-3 6.16191 6173203621171 01:: 63E 466-01 551616131 6321611171? £164 ERIN 9151 1 2 3 .3: UI n: 21.61 42.6011 555:1 271 6. “%Z‘liifl 7361141 ’EJEPI Ii‘l 33611615131 437—16151.” bl“:- °l°ll... (DEEEE E'JDI (215.1111 (312362351111 (4)6161 (5)6132: tit-i 7. “23111-6:- E’rlfi'iig: 91611 $173313*% 701516131 3.1173521] @6151.” E- 0101]... 1111.11 111:9.- %‘Zi6l71l @6161 (1)5812§ '3.“le (2)'.='JEH (3)3Xi 3%”:1 (4)319 (5)5512; {32—1 8. 121—151.15 50.00065— 716— 61 46 3161131 , 514.3 :1 65501] 6161.3. $175311; %— 61611 7l-7—614l6161161? (1) 0-10.000 5.14 (2) 10.000 - 20,0005! (3120. 000 - 30,000.34 (4) 30.000 - 40,000 a (5) 40.000 - 50.000111 >:< 0111161 55-91 L161. 1.0131541 "éé—E? (‘a”) (01) 2. 6431.51.91 LiOIE. (“:1 4ii) 3. 0431.39} 75.61%? ( ) 4. 043151-91 %tZIE? (3H9 $50" 03. 51121512412) 1) CHEM 2) %éE/N 3) 63012.5 4) 7|El ( ) 5. 01:131-1— 71239l 6?. 333 11111 %- ‘F‘iJ—E? (a 5563‘ ‘L d3 03". 19 4 3.5.1.5 1:116:11 0113—111 £5 131612 ’51°1 ZF-fl’tl-‘P- ( ) “"911 ( E ‘9) ‘- 6361611 25.4441 1141636161; 272 i" P. ) ues ionnaire 3* “lei-E" “3% 31% °."+"§2| Type (A 3.6% a); ’ElqziflAlla-ype; >14 0161.321 6 ~1ng 75161 25.3412 Post—Test aa- aa new 6141 5—5. EOIXI. filial-El 5:219! 515% OIEHOII J{iMli‘l “.JQOII %3 X 51% 7|fi§0ll Ell":l Dial-E'- %‘ L. 6134161611 6161 61615—21 131101.). 1:74 6 l L. E 61.61. 634161611 61161 016161-91 41216161 33. 1 1_. 1 31 L. 3.1 2 1 'EISiXI $2! 3| 9125 %flfi' 4 5.1% EHEMIEI EILllll. 2101: 52111 6611412. 01615-91 ’éUZIOI 2 1. 1.1414121 11641416171 614161 filMOICI 2. 61614121 6141616171 614161 a ‘0’5 6ll—‘i‘-i.l*l$>_? A .erU. 525m. WWQ 3W5: ..2 5E MEN ad IEISIXI %Q 1 51410111 A .’.EHlXiE Eéfilf §|AlOI El 7 273 3. ’54:] 2191:3149} 5.116161 151636415101] 6116.} 011615-91 43110111 1:741:3- ‘o'fi 6H 3151:1119? %QiMBI %QfiMBI @658 aflEE 1:117:11: HEEOIEI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 will: EEQOICi 5653 5653 Q PJEXI %Q51 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q ElECl flil61xl %Q 561% Bit mumq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 HMNH $517115 E§61E .’tHleE 5%“:- §|A171 01141:} 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 §IA1OIE1 4. 61:16 6161614161 6.1616 6.346.161 616.1 61616.16 41216111 :53- ‘O’E 611 51541419? 513611614121 EIJEII§IA19I @658 @653 Elliili JHEQOIH 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Ellilli 11§Q0|Cl @6153 64619.18 Q c357“ $1361 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q B551 fl§|611l %Q ’LIEIQ 9.161 6|410ICI 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 511110161 ¢HII1§ EEfi-t— .’tHIXIE Egali- §|A171 01111:) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 6| WM 5. Maxi 514.141.6171 5111...] 616.1 64161 61210lb1 .2416:— 61616111671 @3101 Llfltl 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 @2101 it} HEIQ 4‘- 21121 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 ’LIEIQ 4‘- 91:1 $gamq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 agamq amflq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 gmfiq 6. 6614121 1641416171 614161 6161 616161 1.1716161 £17419: 616161411171 55101 HEB) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 5301 if.) HEIQ 4‘- 21111 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 .‘JEIQ 4‘- 21m egamq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 agamq gmgq 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 imam 274 7.6%1flflfi4W11661W1*14N%L%N’Mmagqm? %Eflluflq 1 2 :3 4 5 6 666*Faq 1 2 3 4 5 6 %QQNH 1 2 3 4 5 6 QNEG 1 2 3 4 5 6 8. ”31%| 6.1133146] c1161 C1119] ”$210111 1:793 %Emliflq 1 2 :3 4 5 6 LIEIQ gF 811:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 %QQNU 1 2 3 4 5 6 gmgq 1 2 3 4 5 6 qqqq EQOI gm 1.1ng 4‘- 91111 591615101111 $501361 666666? \lflx‘lq >’< 111% 7lfi§0| "1"}.1 €1§17|91 QQE {‘JNIQE AIQOH ES :r‘UHQ 7156111 914171 %EXI. :1 6152 013110“ K“MEI I=fl§01l 521315” E Etfl 9151:1412. 01113591 QQOI EE- 3—‘1‘ Ii'lOIKI 53.53 535-51 £19.17“ QQSW 91224. %‘flfi' 4 312 5161MB 1511—1121. 1. ’35! 11161615171 411151666... $flfifilflllfiu- 1 2 3 4 5 #121613“ 633166 1 2 3 4 5 31121 71-‘32‘JOI 91:1 1 2 3 4 5 2 16111641711317] {11'55‘ $7... $21 $111 6W 31:1 1 2 3 4 5 61216176 33% QG 1 2 3 4 5 'T‘i’J 71EQOI 91151 1 2 w .p. U" 275 %EOI €111 QEIQ -’1‘- 21111 %QQOIQ £01361 Q QIMQEL Olir t'xil x) Nix] \l \‘lfi ?213111 Q51 E‘QQ ad Q61 71%! 71%QOI 91121 512.1 8131 Q 111 :HEJQ ad QE1 719:] 7134801 21111 3.6% 23319;”1’1-‘66... 371946111 QXI 91111 1 2 $21617” 9113 31 Q51 1 2 $61 71§Q0| 21111 1 2 4. 61:13! 2361?; 4111-116- %.. $94311 QXI 9161 1 2 3119:1617“ 93% ad Q61 1 2 $21 71's-Q0I 91111 1 2 X 111° 7|21§0| =1171 BQNE £1218 Oi‘é-a-LIW? 5‘94 Q55 W951: 511011 1.4151311 1115.751517] 31611:: {5161 215-”F6111 Sgt-EH 1 2 3 2. 11164171 113-1441:6171 3141:: 612161 1.151 $612 61x11 2161.1 2 3 66111111 75.6171 3161” {1611 6:461?“ °-:-E1 1 2 3 4 2.61611 63-66617] 61416: 61216.1 1161 $612 E1W3 ‘21 1 1 2 5 ‘66 £116.61 1: 5171617171 {64 -’._r‘--’F61II Sit-C1 1 2 3 3 4 5 6 7 311216111 4.11:1 3 4 5 6 7 $612 31 £61 3 4 5 6 7 311?; 7173-QOI 2M 3 4 5 6 7 $6161.21 4151 3 4 5 7 $213; 31' 2.1121 3 4 6 7 311?; 71EQOI 71121 3 $0111 Q Eo—“r-fim 24:XIOII E1115.1 013156° | 0’11 6116561412. 271 617371+E%... (A) .p. U" 4 5 6 276 212 Elm?! Fl)! -1> 32 SEQ 1161 2". 17.114 1111 1> O3 611 at .29. 1‘3. .191. 2:. 111 r0 Iii 111. 0i 3.131 N -r-‘ 128. -_9-. Q2115. L1%."- 661% £8 %612 61x11 211:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Ulill 9.1111 7. ‘flllil E125§I41E 51171 33173 71717157737... 6161 Eff-616! DIEM Q QJ-EQ 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 65-7-6131 24121 8. 6:16! '21113114170 71 2171171 1161011... 613121 1143 $618 61% $6613 U|X|1 211:1, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 HI I: 21111 >:< 111:. $6101 0413131394 612119-JXI61E 11016 E 6H-.— LIME. 1.7116617311101111 21121611: 67111661 x1116 7.5161 HENRI CHEW 0 51:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 flilflfl 6163-50111 61-3-51 01:1 211.51g 0| 211:1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 21§1610| 1:1 1 £6 51311 66:1 16 61°16 616 2111612- ( ) “"511 ( %1 Q) 4 onggwct 21113121 2.511011 gum—1411 1:11:31” 7JA1fi1Llc1, 277 APPENDIX F KOREAN VERSION OF EXPERIMENTAL STIMULI Stimuli Type A 278 (JIB'I-fil- El 1IIAI LII—g. %% Type A ‘I’J° "I‘fisfl ZS-fJAL‘L) 3373-?- %7i624193°11*1t 519 71%)“ EH? “611% 6.673%}? 611E 3'6 E‘ilé} 2163145} 33733123 fllEt— 71%]94 973303 65119} $716673 71% 65-? 7‘3 E01] [113} 71‘6““ 611711] $76} (“3%, 11%, 113131. 11““)% 75% 11:2: 1?— 3} E 111511145}. 211 6917694 941316 51%44 26%145}. ,2... _.;._H__. u 1? 56.1.1 . W 1 '7' . F7 :1 (336 £37134 9691 7|?3) : 671616716 (26661 O 21,”; aging S‘éfil 275215104 EfEJP—I 266763 HHENJ 91201, 2 2:12} =1.‘ 7 7191 EH7I. 4:6, 621% H1131?“ 2%AI9IIL QEHNS} E93294 11%!2 16126317“ ill-“.5611 21E %EOIL} NEE. ¢~ 7|?E1): 671, 6, M1171 11116. 61 616621 61661 66716011 61¢ 56612 216 661qu 71216. thll (75%: 33171315? 7|“) 6626666 6712I 8H6 31’“ 9J7| $|3H a—lQ‘B—l 3% Hal} EIHIE Afgfiffll 3 £31} £794 %7l, 5, &EI|7I Hflé. §1§f§§21 43%?! i‘flEEQg 64%?“ EC} E‘d 7517“ Sggaé E'Iéaffl 911-1:- %{SOIL} HESS. 279 >6 666'— 676 616116 67666616 «>161 471 716.121 6666 51-8-31 601 616 6766616 61661. 120016 16 66) 1. 66161616666171 66: 66 1666121 219171211 2. 6.16661 $flfl§l7l 66: %éil 166 6.1666 7121) 3. 6126 E16661: 661 16661.21 219—1 7121) 4. 6’3 21666: 661 1616 6666 7121) %‘5’3’31 “.11 (61:1 ‘66 "121) %‘5‘3’3: 6:1 (’51-:- 62.161794) "EU! Fulflfli‘wl ilk} 59:13] 319'; Elk} 61111 6161616171 616121 111.1611 61 a 61616 616 316121 111661 610.1616, mfl£%,%fl 6666,262 66 6.6171 666 671616 6161. 311'! 3313’} H] 111511 ""1 5:. O 1.11 ~11 <21 91 610.1, 911-611 3611 0111. v1 11 1.11 11 .11 10111 011 616-6 62.1% 1 671 6161 111.111 :1 6 6916 01 6101161 1111 6%.] %%£‘§%7§fl 3126 1331313913}. 7. ~ 1’: T ‘3 61‘ 21 21- 61 1.116160] 71111 016, 3.31.31 91 61161 11.161 601 12611 016 6 6— I] QM} w-flflflfl 33149} 38¢! £115 5141:: 21% 3612} flflfl %fifl’éfl? 6 6166161, 0% 916661 66.16 2161 11.11 666161011 616612.32. 6x16 61 6 3'1‘Vé~?~’r— 616160111. 01 616166 2 60.1 6216 61111 6 76661 216121 6161 71-6616 61 614101 73.14131} 6.9.61, 21 6 67361631 6766. 6, 631511711 3116 613:16-96 2161616:— %— 67666011 31% 667661 6 716601111. (X13. iii: 3%?- Egéfifla Eggfllh 1998-20005 7l-E) 280 >6 W7} 6.166 4711 7166 19986161 2000de 61111 67166716 (2666 11016 6116761) 6617166.— 51-3—34 611:1. 1_ 31111751616LL§17I 73—6 (Hyundai): - 159 2. 7341373761 $QE§17I £16! (Samsung): 109 3. $33" 1311111 73%! (Binggrae): ~136 4. 656:! 31:5 8%! (Nongsim): 125 386 7|$1 El. 73 1| 1*(Corporate Environmental Index) 1' ngHF 0: £7} EH7I. 45E. E2} 2% 6487|Eil * Bail?- -100= £7} CH7I. 457%, E2} 2‘551-8 7I-E7‘I 5- HH9—I EQE 54% E‘IEEF @913 * 13% XI?- 100: :67} UPI. 453 5%} 2% 34% 7|§il I.39—l 2%EQ 3 5:32}? @9- Corporate E nvironmental Index 15° "W 125 '“11”—1 m 109 . y - 1' "(:2 100 7 E z 2 50 . 7 8 lSamsung E 12 0 7 7 1 ' . :5: g Samsung Nongsim - ”“95”" to I 9 as '50 7 . , S c "2’ —100 , ' C ‘ ~ g . . . 'g -150 -136 UJ 459' ' ' i -200 Company (* For the purpose of microfilming this paper, the labels ”Hynudai and "Binggrae" were removed from the chart above so that the chart is different from original one used in the experiment.) 281 Stimuli Type B (21181-11 113'. 611111 Luggg Type 321% "l‘i‘jafl 25-’;}*l.9_) 282 BEE; 61666166161: 6:1 71661 :16 616 666.16” 71166 6661 66-116. 6666 7116-:— 7166 6666 6616 67166716 66 .601 66 71661 1117161 616 (:16, 66, 2631. 66116 6 616.- 66611 6:— 71166116. 21 6166 6111-1:— 6166 66—116. 1 1.12117 1 5‘71014111 91“.?! 7H2) :271Ea7l-ffi- (2636 ‘33 31% iDS ”SE—IN illfiloi Cl%4‘9-| Egfifli Hfléfill 219-01. 3 all 27M EH7| Tfl. E‘c’fS 137-lat?“ Slfiklilll éflfilfiIQl i'fliP—l >166 612161711 666: 66- 66016 6215. l— mat (:Zgl7l—ff- 21:—#— 7I21): 37L 5. 61.6l7l 8H3. 61 gr SQI’J Elfii-l 357F150" 54¢ E‘a‘filfl 21=§él0|l4 7M5. 2.2/3! £42 3:32; 51:6: 7161); 66262663 716 HHE 5W 9J7| $I3H 544994 85 7|§El QHIS Algalfll :1 all E7194 87L E. .*_*E!||7| HHS. ilélfiflll 3E3 iflflgQg 348’“ EC} fl‘d 7547“ Eggflé E‘Iéfill RAE %QOIH ”21%. 283 >:< 66—11— 3375‘72‘1311511 %Zfi‘igl‘flrl‘c 01311 47H 71%194 %XJé-é- 51-3-34 €01 41176} Q736V3€3 141E515}. (200151 1% 311.1%) 1. 134951” Ttflifll 735*: 5%! 9‘5”.“ 612151 E15531 (3531-74 949M521) Edam-$165.3!” '38: %4‘4 (E; 33%;; 7%) (5643' BEE-35‘: £2! (35171-74 9191 7|21) 55.31 (51-3 Egifi 7|Zl) 33‘3””? ”F“ (% 20 '5 °-t'=-1 “'21) 66316: 66 (7216 621617121) I.— 66 517—6166 66 6121 Elk} EDI Eilfl’fliwl ilk} 511355! 315 Elk} 314%: 11% ’1’7 I}! ‘61 I137} 7] 216 366 11 713%, %311 fiflE’él, 1313’— ”3°13 1’5- if?! 673366 6° 61619} 3&4“! 61"! $1.56] ”363111—11, EH 31617] 66- 26716171 361:}. 321 361.11.} a] 511 ~51] 1;] 5?: 13 x] g), :6 13116 91 6'11 (1.}; 911?} E? ‘2} 6.16-EEO] 36H 016‘, 31>: 51-71 :66 616151.10] 101111 01.601, :11 E11"?! 1111 6 7611 016 :16 r 66 1 9] 613 $16-$10] 121111 01% {”671 51212: ‘ 6:561! :1 51‘— °66 016— 666161 1111 9113113515}. 551‘}! 16616671 311/454 filial a} ‘5 514% Xl‘rl 367d 34’69} 5678?.«73 7166- 61681111, 0% 9.0366 66-8.- OI'ESH 4L“ fl'fg 411.3]01] 21411.10‘3; 31:1} 6 8H9 5E739-7’1‘7 §I*Hi 01C}. 0] 314-3—8- Zl %‘fl %7-‘1351 *HH 6} 731311] 2163+ 521% 716711-3- 15} ilk/‘16] 7517’???“ 96°01, 211% 67331-611} @736 .6511?" 3313 *}°d‘é°11%13}lr: 6 %fiiidl 34%" %Vani %fE- 7l°d%°l'4. (113 iii: 86-?- Eaéfifla 8537121, 1998-2000's.! 7|?) 284 X Eilciigilifie 733-5333 fiofiofiflflt iii-iii 4711 719394 1998011/‘1 ZOOOEE 4°] 51V}??? 71%:- (3‘337‘6 “J26“ 31%i1) jail]??? ‘31773—34' €13}. 1. 138757” $flfi§i7l 2'5! (Hyundai): - 159 2. SACHS” g'flfiflfl %é! (Samsung): 109 3. 616 315 2756+ (Binggrae): —136 4. 61:18:11 E131 %Q (Nongsim): 125 X 7| 33 E} fiXII"(Corporate Environmental Index) * ngl-i- 01 ='=1“7PEH7|. 515$, 5%} 2% 3487I-fi-il * 35.1%“?- —100: €1.17} I3H7l, -’1‘-§, 5%} 2%618 7|Eil 1=- HH94 SEE Q3 “32? @93— * Ea XI?- 100: ='67} EH7I. $761. 521‘ 2% 51% 7l-Exl E994 295.3% g %Ié’fl @513- Corporate Environmental Index 150 7 125 _ 109 g 100 § 2 50 A 8 FIHyiJnd; 1 C _ __ _____1____ . ‘ %- g 0 . . ' Iamggrae I E 'g Hyundal Binggrae , . ° 2 -50 E 9 ‘0 1 a C a -100 1 ‘ 1 2 E -150 1 —136 1 W 459 1 -200 ~ - , . ~ ._._. , -‘ Company (* For the purpose of microfilming this paper, the labels "Samsung" and "Nongsim" were removed from the chart above so that the chart is different from original one used in the experiment.) BIBLIOGRAPHY 286 . Lml_ __._ BIBLIOGRAPHY Afsah, S. (2002). PROPER (Program for Pollution Control Evaluation and Rating): A Model for Promoting Environmental Compliance and Strengthening Transparency and Community Participgtion in Developing Countries. World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr [2002, 4/2]. Afsah, S., Laplante, B., & Makarim, N. (1996). Programme-Based Pollution Control Management: The Indonesian PROKASIH Programme. Asian Journal of Environmental Management, 4 (November)(2), 75-93. Afsah, S., Laplante, B., Shaman, D., & Wheeler, D. (1997, July). Creating Incentives to Control Pollution, [DEC Notes]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Afsah, S., Laplante, B., & Wheeler, D. (1996). Controlling Industrial Pollution: A New Paradigm (No. 1672 PRD working paper). Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/1672/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Afsah, S., Laplante, B., & Wheeler, D. (1997, March). Regulation In The Information Age: Indonesian Public Information Program For Environmentgl Management. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 6/5]. Afsah, S., & Vincent, J. R. (1997, March). Putting Pressure on Polluters: Indonesig'g PROPER program. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 6/5]. Afsah, S., & Wheeler, D. (1996). Indonesia's New Pollution Control Program: Using Public Pressure to Get Compliance. East Asian Executive Reports, 18(6), 9-12. Ajzen, I. (1985). From Intention to Actions: A Theory of Planned Behavior. In J. Kuhl & J. Beckmann (Eds.), Action Control: From Cognition to Behavior (pp. 11-39). New York: Springer-Verlag. Ajzen, I. (1988). Attitudes, Personality. and Behavior. Chicago: Dorsey. Ajzen, I. (1991). The Theory of Planned Behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 50, 179-211. Ajzen, I., & Fishbein, M. (1980). Understanding Attitudes and Predicting Social Behavior. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall Inc. 287 Anderson, L. W. (1988). Attitudes and their Measurement. In J. P. Keeves (Ed.), Educational research, methodology, and measurement: an intemationalhandboolg. Oxford, England: Pergamon Press. APA. (1997). Publication Manual of the American Psychological Association (4th ed.). Washington, DC: American Psychological Association. Aronson, B., Turner, J. A., & Carlsmith, J. M. (1963). Communicator Credibility and Communication Discrepancy as Determinants of Opinion Change. Journal of Abnormal aLd Social Psychology, 67, 31-36. Arora, S., & Cason, T. N. (1995). An Experiment in Voluntary Environmental [ Regulation: Participation in EPA's 33/50 Program. J oumad of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(3), 271-286. Arora, S., & Cason, T. N. (1996). Why Do Firms Volunteer to Exceed Environmental Regulations? Understanding Participation in EPA's 33/50 program. Land Economics, 72(4), 413-432. Arora, S., & Gangopadhyay, S. (1995). Toward a Theoretical Model of Voluntary Overcompliance. J oumal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28, 289-309. Associated Press. (1991, June 9). Presbyterians Ratify Teaching on Sex, Ecology. Boston Globe, pp. 4. Badrinath, S. G., & Bolster, P. J. (1996). The Role of Market Forces in EPA Enforcement Activity. J oumial of Regulatory Economics, 10(2), 165-181. Bagozzi, R. P. (1994). Measurement in Marketing Research: Basic Principles of Questionnaire Design. In R. P. Pagozzi (Ed.), Principles of Mag‘etig Research (pp. 149). Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Publisher. Bagozzi, R. P., Baumgartner, H., & Yi, Y. (1991). Coupon Usage and the Theory of Reasoned Action. In R. H. Holman & M. R. Solomon (Eds.), Advances in Consumer Resear_ch_ (Vol. 18, pp. 24-27). Provo, Utah: Association for Consumer Research. Batie, S. S. (1997). Environmental Issues, Policy and the Food Industry. In L. T. Wallace & W. R. Schroder (Eds), Perspectives on Food Industry/Govemment Linkages. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Batie, S. S., & Ervin, D. E. (1997, June 8-9). Flexible Incentives for Environmental Management in Agriculture: A typology. Paper presented at the Flexible Incentives for the Adoption of Environmental Technologies in Agriculture, Greenbelt, Maryland, Gainesville, Florida. 288 Berberoglu, G., & Tosunoglu, C. (1995). Exploratory and Confirmatory Factor Analyses of an Environmental Attitude Scale (EAS) for Turkish University Students. _T_h§ Journal of Environmental Education, 26(3), 40-43. Bettman, J. R. (1979). An Information ProcessLng Theory of Consumer Choice. MA: Addison-Wesley Company. Blacconiere, W. G., & Northcut, W. D. (1997). Environmental Information and Market Reactions to Environmental Legislation. Journal of Accounting, Auditing_& Finance, 12(2, Spring), 149-178. Blackman, A., & Bannister, G. J. (1998). Community Pressure and Clean Technology in the Informal Sector: An Econometric Analysis of the Adoption of Propane by Traditional Mexican Brickmakers. Journal of Environmental Economics an__d Management, 35(1), 1-21 . Boniface, D. R. (1995). Experiment design and stfistical methods for behavioral and social research. London; New York: Chapman & Hall. Booth, W. C., Colomb, G. G., & Williams, J. M. (1995). The Crafi of Reseafl. Chicago: The University of Chicago. Borenstein, S., & Zimmerman, M. B. (1988). Market Incentives for Safe Commercial Airline Operation. American Economic Review, 78(5), 913-935. Bovee, C. L., & Arends, W. F. (1992). Contemporary Advertising. Homewood, IL.: Irwin. Brown, S. P., & Stayrnan, D. M. (1992). Antecedents and Consequences of Attitude Toward the Ad: A Meta Analysis. Journal of Consumer Research, 19(June), 34-51. Brucks, M. (1985). The Effects of Product Class Knowledge on Information Search Behavior. Journal of Conaumer Research, 12(June), 1-16. Bruner, G. C. I., & Hensel, P. J. (Eds). (1992). Marketing Scales Handbook: A Compilation of Multi-Item Measures. Chicago, IL: American Marketing Association. Bryant, B. (1995). Environmental Justice: Issue, Policies and Solutions. Washington, DC: Island Press. Burros, M. (1996, 7 February). A New Goal beyond Organic: Clean Food. New York Times, pp. B1, B5. Cahill, L. B., & Kane, R. W. (1994). Corporate Environmental Performance Expectation in the 19908: More than Just Compliance. Total Oualifl Environmental Managgnent, 3, 409-420. 289 Calder, B. J ., Phillips, L. W., & Tybout, A. M. (1981). Designing Research For Application. Journal of Consumer Resea_r_ch, 8(September), 197-207. Caldwell, L. K. (1990). Between Two Worlds: Science, the Environmental Movement, and Policy Choice. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Campbell, D. T., & Stanley, J. C. (1963). Experimeni and Quasi-Experimental Desiggs for Research. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co. Chan, T. S. (1996). Concern for Environmental Issues and Consumer Purchase Preferences: A Two-Country Study. Journal of International Conflmer Marketing, 9(1), 43-55. Che, Y. K., & Earnhart, D. (1997). Optimal Use of Litigation: Should Regulatory Information Be Withheld to Deter Frivolous Suits? Rand J oumal of Economics, 28, 120-134. Clifford, M. (1990). Kicking Up a Stink: South Korean Government Reels from Anti- Pollution Backlash. Far Eastern Economic Review, October 18, 72-73. Cohen, M. A. (1998). Monitoringand Enforcement of Environmentafl’olicy. [Working paper of World Bank]. Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/workJaper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Cohen, M. A., Fenn, S. A., & Nairnon, J. S. (1995). Environmental and Finflcial Performance: Are They Related? Washington, DC: Investor Responsibility Research Center, Environmental Information Service. Cook, T. D., & Campbell, D. T. (1979). Quasi-Experimentation: Design & Analysis Issues for Field Settings Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co. Cormier, D., Magnan, M., & Morard, B. (1993). The Impact of Corporate Pollution on Market Valuation: Some Empirical Evidence. Ecological Economics, 8, 135-155. Cote, J ., & Tanushaj, P. S. (1989). Culture Bound Assumptions in Behavior Intention Models. In T. Srull (Ed.), Advances in Consumer Resea_r_c_h (Vol. 16, pp. 105-109). Provo, Utah: Association for Consumer Research. Creswell. (1994). Research Desig: QualitzLive & Qumfigative Approaches Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Cropper, M. L., Simon, N. B., Alberini, A., & Sharma, P. K. (1997, December). I_h_§ Health Effects of Air Pollution in Deth India, [No. 1860 PRD Working Paper]. The Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/workjaper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Crowne, D. P., & Marlowe, D. (1964). The Approval Motive. New York: Wiley. 290 Dasgupta, S. (1999, November). Opportunities for ImprovingEnvironmental Compliance in Mexico, [No. 2245, World Bank Discussion Paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Dasgupta, S., Hettige, H., & Wheeler, D. (1997, December). What Improves Environmental Performance? Evidence from Mexican Industry, [No. 1877 PRD Working Paper]. Policy Research Department of Word Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 6/5]. Dasgupta, S., Huq, M., & Wheeler, D. (1997, February). Bending the Rules: Discretionary Pollution Control in China, [NO. 1716 PRD Working Paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., & Mamingi, N. (1998, April). Capital Market Responses To Environmental Performance In Developing Countries, [No. 1909 PRD Working Paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., & Meisner, C. (1998, March). Environmental News in Argentina, Chile, Mexico and the Philippines, [Executive Summary]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Dasgupta, S., Lucas, R. E. B., & Wheeler, D. (1997, November). Small Plafnts, Pollution and Poverty: New Evidence from Brazil and Mexico, [No. 2029 PRD Working Paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Dasgupta, S., & Wheeler, D. (1996, November). Citizen Complaints a‘s Environmental Indicators: Evidence fi'om China. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/compwp/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Davis, J. J. (1994). Consumer Response to Corporate Environmental Advertising. J oumal of Coasumer Marketing, 11, 25-47. Deily, M. B., & Gray, W. B. (1991). Enforcement of Pollution Regulations on a Declining Industry. Journal of Environmental Economics yd Management, 21, 260-274. Deutsch, C. (1998, 19 July). For Wall Street, Increasing Evidence That Green Begets Green. New Yogr Times, pp. A7. Donaton, S., & Fitzgerald, K. (1992). Polls Show Ecological Concerns is Strong. Advertising Age, 63, 49. 291 Eagly, A. H., & Chaiken, S. (1993). The Psychologyof Attitudes. Fort Worth: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich. Environmental Protection Agency. ( 1 99 1). Environmental Education. EPA Journal, 1 7(4). Environmental Protection Agency. (1997). EPA Green Lights Program Snapshot for January 1997. Washington, DC: Environmental Protection Agency. Fazio, R. H., Powell, M. C., & Williams, C. J. (1989). The Role of Attitude Accessibility in the Attitude-to-Behavior Process. Journal of Consumer Research, 16(December), 280-288. F eldman, S., Soyka, P., & Ameer, P. (1996). Does Improvinga Firm's Environmental Management System and Environmental Performance Result in a Higher Stock Price? Fairfax, Va.: ICF Kaiser International. Fialka, J. J. (1998, May 4). EPA Puts Records About Polluters On the Internet. Wall Street J oumd, pp. A8. Fishbein, M. (1967). Attitude and the Prediction of Behavior. In M. F ishbein (Ed.), Readirgs in Attitude Theory and Measurement. New York: Wiley. Fishbein, M. (1980). A Theory of Reasoned Action: Some Applications and Implications. In J. H. E. Howe & M. M. Page (Eds), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation, 1979 (Vol. 27, pp. 65-116). Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press. Fishbein, M., & Ajzen, I. (1975). Belief, Attitude, Intention and Behavior: An Introduction to Theory and Research. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Fishbein, M., & Ajzen, I. (1977). Attitude-Behavior Relations: A Theoretical Analysis and Review of Empirical Research. Psychological Bulletin, 84(September), 888- 918. Fisher, A., McClelland, G. H., & et al. (1991). Communicating the Risk from Radon. Journal of the Air & Waste Management Association, 41(11), 1440-1445. F ombrun, C. J. (1996). Reputation. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Foulon, J ., Lanoie, P., & Laplante, B. (1999, October). Incentives for Pollution Control: _R_egulation and I?) or (?). Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Frankel, C., & Coddington, W. (1994). Environmental Marketing. In R. Kolluru (Ed.), Environmental Strategies Handbook (pp. 643-677). New York: McGraw-Hill. Gabel, H. L., & Sinclair-Desgagne, B. (1993). Managerial Incentives and Environmental Compliance. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24, 229-240. 292 General Accounting Office. (1987). Hazardous waste: facility inspections are not thorough and complete (Report RCED-88-20). Washington DC. General Accounting Office. (1991). Environment enforcement: penalties may not recover economic benefitwined by violators (Report RCED-91-166). Washington DC. General Accounting Office. (1993). Environmental enforcement: EPA cannot ensure the accuracy of self-reported compliance monitoring data (Report RCED-93-21). Washington DC. General Accounting Office. (1994). Toxic substances: EPA needs more reliable source reduction data and progress measures (Report to the Chairman, Subcommittee on Health and the Environment, Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives). Washington DC. Gerstenzang, J. (1997, 21 November). Survey Bolsters Global Warming Fight. lg flgeles Times, pp. A4. Goldberg, M. E., & Hartwick, J. (1990). The Effects of Advertiser Reputation and Extremity of Advertising Claim on Advertising Effectiveness. Journal of Consumer Research, 17(September), 172-179. Goldsmith, R. E. (1987). Two Students of Yeasaying. Psychological Reports, 60, 239- 244. Goodman, A., & Streeter, A. (1999). Companies of the Year. Tomorrow, 9(1), 14-16. Gray, D. B., Borden, R. J., & Weigel, R. H. (1985). Ecolgical Beliefs and Behaviors: Assessment and Change. Westport, CN: Greenwood Press. Green, D. P., & Cowden, J. A. (1992). Who Protests: Self-Interest and White Opposition to Busing. Journal of Politics, 54, 471-496. Greenwald, M., & Katosh, J. P. (1987). How to Track Changes in Attitudes. American Demographics, August, 46. Gresser, J. (1979). Managing Industrial Development with Environmental Management in the Republic of Korea (Report No. 79-3): World Bank, Urban and Regional Economics Division. Grodsky, J. A. (1993). Certified Green: The Law and Future of Environmental Labeling. The Yale Journal on Regulation, 10, 147 -227. Hamilton, J. T. (1995). Pollution as News: Media and Stock Market Reactions to the Toxics Release Inventory Data. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(1), 98-113. 293 Hamilton, J. T. (1996). Going by the (Informal) Book: The EPA's Use of Informal Rules in Enforcing Hazardous Waste Laws. In R. Pethig (Ed.), Conflicts and Cooperation in Managing Environmental Resources. New York: Springer-Verlag. Hanrahan, D., Wheeler, D., Keene, M., & Shaman, D. (1998). Develoging Partnerships for Effective Pollution Management. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Harford, J. D. (1997). Frim Ownership Patterns and Motives for Voluntary Pollution Control. Managerial and Decision Economics, 18(6), 421-432. Hartman, R. S., Huq, M., & Wheeler, D. (1997, December). Why Paper Mills Clean Up: Determinants of Pollution Abatement in Four Asian Countries, [No. 1710 PRD working paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm. Hartman, R. S., Wheeler, D., & Singh, M. (1994, December). The Cost of Air pollution Abatement, [No. 1398 PRD working paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/compwp/index.htrn [2000, 5/ 1 7]. Helland, E. (1998). The Enforcement of Pollution Control Laws: Inspections, Violations, and Self-Reporting. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 141-153. Henderson, G. V. (1990). Problems and Solutions in Conducting Events Studies. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 93(3), 282-306. Hettige, H., Hug, M., Pargal, S., & Wheeler, D. (1996). Determinants of Pollution Abatement in Developing Countries: Evidence from South and Southeast Asia. World Development, 24 (December)(12), 1891-1904. Hoffman, A. (1993). Who Loves Love Canal. Tomorrow, 3(3), 58-64. Hoffman, A. (1996). A Strategic Response to Investor Activism. Sloan Management Review, 37(2), 51-64. Hoffman, A. J. (2000 a). Competitive Environmental Strategy: A Guide to the Changi_ng Business Landscape. Washington, DC: Island Press. Hoffman, A. J. (2000 b). Integrating Environmental and Social Issues into Corporate Practice. Environment, 42(5), 22-33. Hofrichter, R. (Ed.). (1993). Toxic Struggles: The Theory and Practice of Environmental Justice. Philadelphia, PA: New Society Publishers. Holbrook, M. B., & Havlena, W. J. (1988). Assessing the Real-to-Artificial Generalizability of Multi-attribute Attitude Models in Tests of New Product Designs. Journal of Marketing Research, 25(February), 25-35. 294 Hunter, J. E., Danes, J. E., & Cohen, S. H. (Eds). (1984). Mathematical Models of Attitude Changflnd Coflive Structures. Orlando: Academic Press. Hunter, J. E., & Gerbing, D. W. (1982). Unidimensional Measurement, Second Order Factor Analysis, and Causal Models. In B. M. Staw & L. L. Cummings (Eds), Research in Organizational Behavior (pp. 267-320). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, Inc. Hunter, J. E., Gerbing, D. W., Cohen, S. H., & Nicol, T. S. (1980). PACKAGE 1980; A System of FORTRAN Routines for the Analysis of Correlational Data. Waco, TX: Baylor University. Hunter, J. E., Levine, R. L., & Sayres. (1984). Attitude Change in Hierarchical Belief Systems and its Relationship to Persuasibility, Dogmatism, and Rigidity. In J. E. Hunter & J. E. Danes & S. H. Cohen (Eds), Mathematical Models of Attitude Change and Cognitive Structures. Orlando: Academic Press. Huq, M., & Wheeler, D. (1993). Pollution Reduction Without Formal Regulation: Evidence from Bangghglesh, [No. 1993-39 PRD working paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: 9" www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. J affe, A., . B., Portney, S. R., Portney, P. R., & Stavins, R. (1995). Environmental Regulation and the Competitiveness of US. Manufacturing. Journal of Economic Literature, 33(1), 132-163. J eon, G. J. (1998). Information as a Policy Tool: A Flexible Means of Improving Environmental Oaality in Korea. Unpublished Ph. D. Dissertation, Naderbilt University. Jones, J. D., Jones, C. L., & Phillips-Partick, F. (1994). Estimating the Costs of the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill. Research in Law and Economics, 16, 109-150. Kassaye, W., & Verma, D. (1992). Balancing Traditional Packaging Functions with the New Green Packaging Concerns. Advanced Management Journal, 57, 15-23. Katz, J. (1994). Levi Straus & Co.: Global Sourcing. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard Business School. Kaufman, L. (1999). Selling green: What Managers and Marketers Need to Know about Consumer Environmental Attitudes. Environmental Quality Maflgement, 8(4, summer), 1 1-20. Kennedy, P. W., & Laplante, B. (1995, August). Equilibrium Incentives for Adopting Cleaner Technology Under Emissions Pricing. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 6/5]. 295 Kennedy, P. W., Laplante, B., & Maxwell, J. (1994). Pollution Policy: The Role for Publicly Provided Information. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26(1), 31-43. Keppel, G. (1991). Desig and Analysis: A Researcher's Handbook. Englewood Cliffs, NJ .: Prentic-Hall, Inc. Kerr, K. (1990). Thinking Green is No Longer a Hippie Dream. AdWeek‘s Marketing Week, 31,18-19. Khanna, M., Quimio, W. R. H., & Bojilova, D. (1998). Toxics Release Information: A Policy tool for Environmental Protection. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 36(3, November), 243-266. Kiker, C. F., & Putz, F. E. (1997). Ecological Certification of Forest Products: Economic Challenges. Ecological Economics, 20, 37-51. Klassen, R. D., & McLaughlin, C. P. (1996). The Impact of Environmental Management on Firm Performance. Management Science, 42, 1199-1214. Knight, R. (1998). Profits and Principles: Does There Have To Be a Choice? London: Shell International Ltd. Konar, S., & Cohen, M. A. (1997). Information as Regulation: The effect of Community Right to Know Laws on Toxic Emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics aLd Managgment, 32(1), 109-124. Krupp, F. (1990). Win/W in on the Environmental Front. EPA Journal, 16(5). Kuhn, R. G., & Jackson, E. L. (1989). Stability of Factor Structures in the Measurement of Public Environmental Attitudes. The Journal of Environmental Educziion, 20(3), 27-33. Lafferty, B. A., & Goldsmith, R. E. (1999). Corporate Credibility's Role in Consumers' Attitudes and Purchase Intensions When a High versus a Low Credibility Endorser Is Used in the Ad. Journal of Business Research, 44, 109-116. Laffont, J. J. (1989). The Economics of Uncertainty and Information. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Lanoie, P., Laplante, B., & Roy, M. (1997). Can Capital Markets Create Incentives For Pollution Control? Ecological Economics, 26, 31-41. Laplante, B., & Lanoie, P. (1995). Market Response to Environmental Incidents in Canada: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. Southern Economic Journal, 60(3), 657-672. 296 Laroche, M., Kim, C., & Zhou, L. (1996). Brand Familiarity and Confidence as Determinants of Purchase Intention: An Empirical Test in a Multiple Brand Context. Journal of Business Research, 37(October), 115-120. Lavelle, T. J. (1994). Federal Agencies in the Realm of Pollution Prevention and Community Right-to-Know. Federal Facility Environmental J ustice, 5(4), 489-510. Lavine, H. J ., Huff, W., Wagner, S. H., & Weeney, D. (1998). The Moderating Influence of Attitude Strength on the Susceptibility to Context Effects in Attitude Surveys. Jom'nal of Personality and Social Psychology, 75, 359—373. Lee, C. (1993). Beyond Toxic Wastes and Race, Confronting Environmental Racism: Voices from the Grassroots (pp. 41-52). Boston, MA: Bullard, Robert D., South End Press. Leeming, F. C., Dwyer, W. O., & Bracken, B. A. (1995). Children's Environmental Attitude and Knowledge Scale: Construction and Validation. The Journal of Environmental Education, 26(3), 22-31. Ir Livemois, J ., & McKenna, C. J. (1998). Truth or Consequences: Enforcing Pollution Standards with Self-Reporting. Journal of Public Economics. Lynn, F. M. (1990). Public Participation in Risk Management Decisions: The Right to Define, the Right to Know and the Right to Act. Risk-Issue Health SAF., 1(2), 95- 101. Mackenzie, S. B., & Lutz, R. J. (1989). The Role of Attitude Toward the Ad as a Mediator of Advertising Effectiveness: A Test of Competing Explanations. Journal of Marketing Research, 23(May), 130-143. MacKinlay, A. C. (1997). Event Studies in Economics and Finance. Journal of Economics Literature, 35(1), 13-39. McKinney, M. J. (2000). What Do we Mean by Consensus? In P. Brick & D. Snow & S. V. D. Wetering (Eds), Crossing the Great Divide (pp. 33-41). Washington DC: Island Press. Magat, W. A., & Viscusi, W. K. (1990). Effectiveness of the EPA's Regulatory Enforcement: The Case of Industrial Effluent Standards. Journal of Law & Economics, 33, 331-360. Magat, W. A., & Viscusi, W. K. (1992). Inforrfltional Approaches to Regplation. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Malik, A. S. (1990). Markets for Pollution Control When Firms are Non-Compliant. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18(2), 97-106. 297 Maloney, M. P., Ward, M. P., & Braucht, G. N. (1975). A Revised Scale for the Measurement of Ecological Attitudes and Knowledge. American Psychologigt, 30, 787-790. Mani, M., Pargal, S., & Huq, M. (1996, November). Does Environmerg Regulation Matter? Determinants Of The Location Of New Manufifacturingjlants In India_In_ 12241, [No. 1718 PRD Working Paper]. The Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Marcinowski, F., & Napolitano, S. (1993). Reducing the Risks from Radon. Air & Waste, 43, 955-962. McCoy, C. (1998, 11 February). Two US. Members of Mitsubishi Group and Environmental Activists Resch Pact. Wall Street Journal, pp. A8. McGuire, W. J. (Ed.). (1969). The Nature of Attitudes and Attitude Change (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: Addison-Wesley. Mellor, M. (1993). Building a New Vision: Feminist, Green Socialism. In R. Hofi'ichter (Ed.), Toxic Struggles: The Theory and Practice of Environmental Justice (pp. 36- 46). Philadelphia, PA: New Society Publishers. Miller, D., & Ratner, R. K. (1998). The Disparity Between the Actual and Assumed Power of Self-Interest. Journal of Personalijy and Social Psycholggy, 74, 53-62. Mishra, G. K., Newman, D. P., & Stinson, C. H. (1997). Environmental Regulations and Incentives for Compliance Audits. Journal of Accountiag and Public Policy. 16(2), 1 87-214. Mitchell, A. A., & Olson, J. C. (1981). Are Product Attribute Beliefs the Only Mediator of Advertising Effects on Brand Attitude? Journal of MarketingResearch, 18(August), 318-332. Moscovitz, D. (1993). Green Pricing: Why Not Customer Choice? The Electricity Journal, 6(8), 42-49. Muller, T. E., & Taylor, W. (1991). Everybody Talks about the Environment: But How Environmentally Responsive are Consumers? Marketing-Proceedings of the ASAC Conference, 12(6), 202-211. Muoghalu, M. I., Robison, H. D., & Glascock, J. L. (1990). Hazardous Waste Lawsuits, Stockholder Returns, and Deterrence. Southern Economic J oumal(October 1990), 357-370. Nash, J., & Ehrenfeld, J. (1996). Code Green: Business Adopts Voluntary Environmental Standards. Environment(January/February), 16-20, 36-45. 298 Naysnerski, W., & Tietenberg, T. (1992). Private Enforcement. In T. H. Tietenberg (Ed.), Innovation in Environmental Policy (pp. 109-136). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Naysnerski, W., & Tietenberg, T. (1992). Private Enforcement of Federal Environmental Law. Land Economics, 68(1), 28-48. Newell, S. J. (1993). Developing a Measurement Scale and a Theoretical Model Defining Corporate Credibility and Determining Its Role as an Antecedent of Consumers' Attitude toward the Advertisement. Unpublished Doctoral Dissertation, Florida State University, Tallahassee. Newhouse, N. (1990). Implications of Attitude and Behavior Research for Environmental Conservation. The Journal of Environmental Education, 22(1), 26-32. Noah, L. (1994). The Imperative to Warn: Disentangling the "Right to Know" fi'om the "Need to Know" about Consumer Product Hazards. Yale Journal of Regplation, 11(2), 293-400. Noye, C., & Das, M. (1993). Does Concerns for Environment Translate into Environmentally Friendly Purchase Behavior? Proceedings of the ASB Conference, 212-223. O'Conor, D. (1995). Managing the Environment with R4apid Industrialisation: Lessons from the East Asiam Experience. Paris: OECD (Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development). OECD. (1991). Environmental labeling in OECD Countries. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Osgood, C. E., & Tannenbaum, P. H. (1955). The Principle of Congruity in the Production of Attitude Change. Psychological Review, 62, 42-55. Ottman, J. (1993). Industry’s Response to Green Consumerism. Journal of Business Strategy, 13, 3-7. Pargal, S., Hettige, H., Manjula Singh, & Wheeler, D. (1997, July). Formal and Informal Regplation of Industrial Pollution: Comparative Evidence from Indonesia_ and the United States, [No. 1797 PRD Working Paper]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Pargal, S., & Wheeler, D. (1996). Informal Regulation of Industrial Pollution Developing Countries: Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 104 (December)(6), 1314. Pattern, D. M. (1998). The Impact of the EPA's TRI Disclosure Program on State Environmental and Natural Resource Expenditures. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 17(winter)(4,5), 367-382. 299 rpa _. .. Paulhus, D. L. (1984). Social Desirable Responding: Some New Solutions to Old Problems. In D. M. Buss & N. Cantor (Eds), Persoaality Psychology: Recent Trends and EmergingDirections (pp. 201-209). New York: Springer Verlag. Pearce, D. W., Markandya, A., & Barbier, E. B. (1989). Blueprint for a Green Economy. London: Earthscan Publications. Pearce, D. W., & Turner, R. K. (1990). Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. Hertfordshire, UK: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Pease, W. S. (1991). Chemical Hazards and the Public's Right to Know: How Effective Is California's Proposition 65? Environment, 33(10), 12-20. Perman, R., Ma, Y., & McGilvray, J. (1996). Natural Resource & Environmental Economics. New York: Longrnan. Prince, J. (1991). Whittling Down Waste. Progressive Grocer, 70, 41-44. PROPER-PROKASIH Team, BAPEDAL, Jakarta, PRDEI, & Bank, W. (1995, November). What is Proper? Reputational Incentives for Pollution Control in Indonesia. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Protess, D. et al. (1987). The Impact of Investigative Reporting on Public Opinion and Policy Making: Targeting Toxic Waste. Public Opinion Ouaterly, 51(2), 166-185. Roddy, G., Cowan, C. A., & Hutchinson, G. (1996). Consumer Attitudes and Behavior to Organic Foods in Ireland. Journal of Intemationagionsumer Marketing, 9(2), 41- 63. Roper Organization Inc. (1990). The Environment: Public Attitudes and Individual Behavior. Rosendahl, I. (1990). Retailers Joining Fight to Clean Up Environment. Drug Topics, 134,(6). Rosenthal, R., & Rosnow, R. L. (1991). Essentials of BehaLioral Research: Methods a_pc_l Data Analysis (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. Russell, C. S. (1990). Monitoring and Enforcement. In P. R. Portney (Ed.), Public Policies for Enviromentflrotection (pp. 243-274). Washington DC: Resources for the Future. Segerson, K., & Tietenberg, T. (1992). The Structure of Penalties in Environmental Enforcement: An Economic Analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 23(2), 179-200. 300 Shane, P. B., & Spicer, H. H. (1983). Market Response to Environmental Information Produce Outside the Firm. The Accounting Review, LVIII, 523-538. Shepard, B. H., Hartwick, J ., & Warshaw, P. R. (1988). The Theory of Reasoned Action: A Meta-Analysis of Past Research with Recommendations for Modifications and Future Research. Journal of Consumer Research, 15(December), 325-343. Shridhar, P. (1996, 4-8 Jan 1996). The Right Research: Measuring the Success and Effectiveness of Public Information Progzams Paper presented at the Conservation '96: Responsible Water Stewardship, Orlando, FL. Smith, R. E., & Swinyard, W. R. (1983). Attitude-Behavior Consistency: The Impact of Product Trial Versus Advertising. Journal of Maaketing Research, 20(August), 257 267. Solomon, M. R. (1992). Consumer Behavior. Boston: Allyn and Bacon. Soros, G. (1998). The Crisis of Global Capitalism: Open Society endangered. New York: Public Affairs Information Service. Spano, S. (2001). Public Dialogue aard Participatory Democracy. Cresskill, NJ: Hampton Press, Inc. Stammer, L. (1997, 9 November). Hanning the Environment Is Sinful, Prelate Says. w Angeles Times, pp. 1A. Steiner, R. L., & Bamhart, R. B. (1972). The Development of an Instrument to Assess Environmental Attitudes Utilizing Factor Analytic Techniques. Science Education, 56(3), 427-432. Stephens, T. (1994). The Concept of Environmental Justice. Sugar Law Center(December), 9-1 0. Sternthal, B., Tybout, A. M., & Calder, B. J. (1994). Experimental Design: Generalization and Theoretical Explanation. In R. P. Bagozzi (Ed.), Principle of Marketing Research (pp. 195-223). Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Publishers. Tietenberg, T. (1985). Emissions Trading: An Exercise in Reforming Pollution Policy. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Tietenberg, T. (1990). Economic Instruments for Environmental Regulation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 6(1), 17-34. Tietenberg, T. (1995). Design Lessons from Existing Air Pollution Control Systems: The United States. In S. Hanna & M. Munasinghe (Eds), Property Rights in a Social and Ecological Context: Case Studies and Design Applications. Washington, DC: The World Bank. 301 Tietenberg, T. (1996). Private Enforcement of Environmental Regulations in Latin America and the Caribbean: An Effective Instrument for Environmental Management? Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. Tietenberg, T. (1998). Disclosure Strategies for Pollution Control. Environmental and Resource Economics, 11, 578-602. Tietenberg, T. (1998, October). Tradable Permits and the Control of Air Pollution in the United State. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/newappr.htm [1998, October]. Tietenberg, T., & Wheeler, D. (1998, October 23-25). EmpoweringThe Community: Information Strategies For Pollution Control. Paper presented at the Frontiers of Environmental Economics Conference, Airlie House, Virginia. Wallace, P. E. (1993). Disclosure of Environmental Liabilities under the Securities Laws: the Potential of Securities-Market-Based Incentives for Pollution Control 50. Washington & Lee Law Review, 50(Summer), 1093. Wang, H., & Wheeler, D. (1996, September). Pricing Industrial Pollution in China: An Econometric Analysis of the Levy System (#1644 PRD working paper). The Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www. worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htm [2000, 4/26]. Wapner, P. (1995). In Defense of Banner Hangers: The Dark Green Politics of Green Peace, Ecolagical Resistance Movements (pp. 300-314): State University of New York Press. Wells, W. D. (1961). The Influence of Yeasaying Response Style. Journal of Advertisiag Research, 1(June), 1-12. Wheeler, D. (1992, January). The Economics of Industrial Pollution Control. World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 6/ 15]. Wheeler, D. (1997, June 27). Information in Pollution Maaagement: The New Model, [No. 16635-BR]. Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: www.worldbank.org/nipr/work_paper/index.htrn [2000, 4/26]. Wheeler, D. (1999). Greeninalndustry: New Poles for Communities, Markets, and Government. New York: Oxford University Press. Wheeler, D., & Afsah, S. (1996). Going Public on Polluters in Indonesia: BAPEDAL's PROPER PROKASIH Program, East Asian Executive Reports (V 01. May 1996). Washington, DC.: International Executive Reports. White, L. (1967). The Historical Roots of Our Ecological Crisis. Science, 155, 1203- 1207. 302 Williams, M. (1992). Environmentally Safe can Enhance Sales. Advertising Age, 63, 8-9. Wimmer, R. D., & Dominick, J. R. (1994). Mass Media Research (4th ed.). Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Pub. Co. Winters, L. C. (1989). Does it Pay to Advertise to Hostile Audiences With Corporate Advertising? Journal of Advertising Research(June/July), 11-18. Woodward, K., & Nordland, R. (1992, 30 November). New Rules for an Old Faith. Newsweek, 71. World Bank. (1998, October 02, 1998). New Ideas in Pollution Regalation (NIPR). Policy Research Department of World Bank. Available: http://www.worldbank.org/nipr/ [2000, 4/26]. World Business Council on Sustainable Development. (1998). Pragmatism Is the Driving Force. Tomorrow, 8(6), 41. Yacoob, M., Brantly, E., & Whiteford, L. (1996). Public Participation in Urban Environmental Management: A Model for Promoting Community-Bag Environmental Management in Peri-Urban Areas (R0103; WASH-TR-90): Camp, Dresser, and McKee International, Inc, Arlington, VA ; Peace Corps, Washington, DC Information Collection and Exchange Div. Yi, Y. (1990). Cognitive and Affective Priming Effects of the Context for Print Advertisements. Journal of Advertising, 19(2), 40-48. Zucarro, C., & Fortin, D. (1992). Reassessing the Socially Responsible Consumer. Marketing-Proceedings of the ASAC Conference, 13(6), 209-217. 303