..).I.J:§.;.a. . :. .. .21 v . , 2: .5: . . . t u t , t a. 3......“ r . , v . .. 3......» V {9 .r I 1F t .1 ‘ r . I: anus... ‘9 3.47 ‘ \ :81 L . XI... 4(3) I ..,...... Lamar...” . .. x .4.) l 1:. I... 1.3K. mini-I:9’ “5.31:. . . .5... l... ‘y s: . . ‘ ,3 o..fl.‘.r.1.fl.§. 5:. . “A" I V This is to certify that the dissertation entitled VOTING RIGHTS, CORPORATE CONTROL, AND FIRM PERFORMANCE presented by Yi Zhang has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph. D. degree in Business Administration W /6M¢A Major plofcssor Date ?/2/2002 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 c:lCIRC/DateDuo.p65-p. 15 VOTING RIGHTS, CORPORATE CONTROL, AND FIRM PERFORMANCE By Yi Zhang A DISSERA'ITION Submitted to Michigan State University In partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Finance 2002 ABSTRACT VOTING RIGHTS, COPORATE CONTROL, AND FIRM PERFORMANCE By Yi Zhang This dissertation investigates the impact of corporate control on firm performance of companies with dual class stock where voting rights are separated from cash flow rights. I first examine the issues concerning the decision to issue multiple classes of common stock with different voting rights. Firms often issue these shares to maintain a concentrated ownership structure, while at the same time raising new equity capital. I identify all Compustat listed companies with dual/multiple class common stock during the 1990-1999 time period using various databases including Compustat, CRSP, proxy statements, and 10-K filings. This database should be the mOst comprehensive sample of dual-class listed firms ever assembled. Using the collected data, I proceed to use logit models to examine which factors affect the likelihood that a firm will issue dual-class shares, and also to see if this relationship has changed over time. My principal findings are as follows: (1) There are strong industry effects in the likelihood of having dual class shares — printing, media, and motion picture firms are relatively more likely to have two classes of common stock while utilities are relatively less likely to do so. (2) Company age affects the likelihood of having a dual-class structure — younger firms are more likely to have two classes outstanding. (3) Firm size does not have any significant effect on the likelihood of having dual—class shares. (4) Firms with high stock-retum volatility are relatively less likely to have a dual class structure. I then examine issues concerning the valuation and performance of dual class firms. I identify insider ownership in dual class firms in 1995 using various databases including proxy statements and lO-K filings. This database should be the most comprehensive ownership data sample of dual-class listed firms ever assembled. I compare valuation and performance of dual class firms and single class firms. I am able to investigate the effects of ownership of voting rights and ownership of cash flow rights on firm value separately. My principal findings are as follows: (1) overall dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms, (2) dual class firms that have both classes traded publicly have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firm and Tobin’s Q increases as insider ownership of cash flow rights rises and declines as insider ownership of voting rights rises, (3) dual class firms that have one class of stock traded publicly do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms, (4) within media industries, dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms while within non-media industries dual class firms have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms, (5) there is no evidence that dual class firms underperform single class peers on certain performance measures, such as the Market-to- book equity ratio and the Price/Earnings ratio. There is some evidence that dual class firms underperform single class peers on some other performance measures, such as ROA, EBIT, and operating cash flow. Of these measures, firm performance rises with insider ownership of cash flow rights and decreases with insider ownership of voting rights, (6) investment-cash flow sensitivities increase with insider ownership of cash flow rights and decrease with insider ownership of voting rights. I explore the implications of these results for our understanding of ownership, control and value. To my past six years. iv ACKNOWLEDGENIENTS I would like to express my thanks to the members of my dissertation committee — Dr. Charles Hadlock (Chair), Dr. Edward Fee, Dr. Wei~Lin Liu, and Dr. Long Chen, for their guidance and encouragement. I especially owe a great deal to Charlie Hadlock for his help, support, patience and commitment of time. Without his guidance I would not have been able to complete this dissertation. I am indebted to Ted Fee, who was always ready to help me with literature, research direction, data analysis and stata. I thank Wei- Lin Liu for consistent encouragement and insightful advice on career development. I thank Long Chen for his valuable advice and critiques of my presentation and many other aspects. I thank Dr. James Wiggins, Dr. Kirt Butler, Dr. Mark Schroder and other faculty members in the Finance department who provided help to me. I am also thankful to Professor Jack Meyer, Professor Jeffrey Wooldridge and Professor Peter Schmidt in the Economics department who taught me economics and econometrics. I thank my fellow students in the finance program for their help and companionship, especially Dr. Romana Sonti, Dr. Wei-Ling Song and Bei Zhou. I also thank Chien-Ho Wang from the economics department for discussions on econometrics. I also thank all of my friends at Michigan State University for supporting me and making my life better. LIST OF TABLES ............................................................................... viii CHAPTER 1 DUAL CLASS STOCK AND THE BENEFITS OF CONTROL .......... 1 l . 1 Introduction ..................................................................... l 1.2 Existing Literature and Hypothesis Development ......................... 3 1.2.1 Existing Literature .................................................... 3 1.2.2 Relationship to Existing Literature ................................. 5 1.2.3 Hypothesis Development ............................................. 6 1.3 Data .............................................................................. 7 1.4 Analysis and results ............................................................ 10 1.4.1 The Logit Mode: Determinants of Dual-class Common Equity and Their Measurements ........................ 10 1.4.2 Results of Logit Analysis ............................................ 13 1.5 Conclusion ..................................................................... 16 CHAPTER 2 DUAL CLASS STOCK, FIRM VALUE AND PERFORMANCE .............................................................. 19 2. 1 Introduction ....................................... , .............................. 19 2.2 Existing Literature and Hypothesis Development .......................... 22 1.2.1 Existing Literature ..................................................... 22 1.2.2 Relationship to Existing Literature .................................. 23 1.2.3 Hypothesis Development ............................................. 24 2.3 Data .............................................................................. 26 2.4 Analysis and Results ............................................................ 29 2.4.1 The Separation of cash flow rights and voting rights .............. 29 2.4.2 Matching of dual class firm with single class firm ................. 32 2.4.3 Cross Sectional Regression of Tobin’s Q ........................... 36 2.4.4 Other Performance Measures ......................................... 44 2.4.5 Dividend policy in dual class firms ................................. 46 2.5 Conclusions ...................................................................... 48 CHAPTER 3 DUAL CLASS STOCK, INVESTMENT, AND CASH FLOW...........51 3. 1 Introduction ...................................................................... 5 1 3.2 Hypothesis Development ...................................................... 52 3.3 Regression Specification ...................................................... 54 3.4 Estimation Results .............................................................. 55 3.5 Conclusion ....................................................................... 56 APPENDICES ..................................................................................... 59 TABLE OF CONTENTS vi Appendix A Tables for Chapter 1: Dual Class Stocks and the Benefit of Control ........................................... 60 Appendix B Tables for Chapter 2: Dual Class Stocks and Firm’s Value and Performance ................................. 74 Appendix C Tables for Chapter 3: Dual Class Stocks, Investment and Cash Flow ........................................... 98 BIBLOGRAPHY .................................................................................. 100 vii Table A1 Table A2 Table A3 Table A4 Table A5 Table A6 Table A7 Table A8 Table A9 Table B1 Table B2 Table 133 Table B4.A Table B4.B Table B4.C Table B4.D Table B4.E Table B4.F Table B5 Table B6.A LIST OF TABLES Number of US Firms With Dual Class Common Stock in 1990-1999 ....... 61 Description of the Variables ...................................................... 62 Summary Statistics for the Sample of Firms in 1990 .......................... 63 Summary Statistics for the Sample of Firms in 1999 ........................... 65 Distribution of Dual Class Firms in Certain Industries in 1990 and 1999.. .67 Logit Regressions for the Sample of Firms in 1990 ............................. 68 Logit Regression for the Sample of Firms in 1990-1994 ..................... 7O Logit Regression for the Sample of Firms in 1995-1999 ..................... 71 Logit Regression for the Sample of Firms in 1999 ............................. 72 Description of the Variables ....................................................... 75 Summary Statistics for the Sample of Firms in 1995 ........................... 76 Distribution of Dual Class Firms in Certain Industries in 1995 ............... 78 Insider Ownership in The Dual Classes .......................................... 79 Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms ........... 79 CEO Ownership in The Dual Classes ........................................... 80 Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms in Media Industries and Non-media Industries ................................. 80 Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms ........... 81 The Largest Block Shareholder Ownership in The Dual Classes ............. 81 Summary Statistics for the Sample of Dual Class Firms and the Matching Firms .................................................................. 82 Summary Statistics for the Sub sample of Dual Class Firms with Both Classes Traded Publicly and the Matching Firms ........................ 83 viii Table B6B Table B7.A Table B7.B Table B8 Table B9 Table B 10 Table B1 1 Table B 12 Table B 13 Table B 14 Table B 15 Table B 16 Table C1 Summary Statistics for the Sub Sample of Dual Class Firms with Only One Class Traded Publicly and the Matching Firms ..................... 84 Summary Statistics for the Sub Sample of Dual Class Firms in Media Industries and the Matching Firms ....................................... 85 Summary Statistics for the Sub Sample of Dual Class Firms in Non—media Industries and the Matching Firms ................................. 86 Cross Sectional Regressions of Q in 1995 ....................................... 87 Cross Sectional Regressions of Q in 1995: Sub Sample when Only The Dual Class Firms Have Both Classes Traded Publicly .................... 89 Cross Sectional Regressions of Q in 1995: Sub Sample of Firms in Media Industries and Firms in Non-media Industries ........................... 90 Regressions of Market-to-book Equity Ratio ................................... 91 Regressions of Price/Earnings Ratio ............................................. 92 Regressions of ROA ................................................................ 93 Regressions of EBIT ............................................................... 94 Regressions of Operating Cash Flow ............................................. 95 Cross Sectional Regressions of DIVIDEND in 1995 .......................... 97 Investment Regressions Results ................................................... 99 ix CHAPTER 1 DUAL-CLASS STOCK AND THE BENEFITS OF CONTROL 1.1 Introduction An important issue in the governance of modem corporations is the structure of managerial incentives. Following the seminal work of Berle and Means (1932), researchers have hypothesized that there are many situations where the preferences of managers and shareholders may substantially diverge. In particular, managers and shareholders may disagree on investment policy (e.g., Jensen (1986)), capital structure policy (e. g., Berger, Ofek, and Yermack (1996)), corporate risk taking (e.g., Amihud and Lev (1981)), and attitudes towards acquisition offers (e.g., Stulz (1988)). One way to solve this agency problem is via the use of incentive compensation and managerial ownership. Consistent with this hypothesis, Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988) demonstrate empirically that managerial ownership may raise firm value by solving agency problems. However, their analysis indicates that there may be both costs and benefits to high managerial ownership. While high ownership may enhance a manager’s incentive to act in shareholders interests, it may also entrench managers by giving them the ability to insulate themselves from outside market forces (e. g., unwanted acquisition attempts). One interesting situation where increased ownership does not necessarily increase both a manager’s degree of entrenchment and his economic incentive to raise firm value arises in the context of dual-class share structures. For firms that adopt this ownership form, cash flow rights and voting rights are partially separated. Thus, by studying dual-class firms, we may be able to better understand some of the components of the costs and benefits to managerial ownership. In this paper I conduct an analysis of firms that adopt a dual-class share structure. While many existing studies have looked at the share price levels and behavior of dual- class stock, no study has carefully examined the factors underlying the decision to adopt a dual-class structure. Using a comprehensive sample of almost all publicly traded firms in the US. over the 1990-1999 time period, I conduct a logit analysis which predicts which types of firms choose to adopt the dual-class structure. Following the work of Demsetz and Lehn (1985), I hypothesize that dual-class structures will be more likely when a firm’s control potential (i.e., the potential managerial benefit from control) is high or when the costs Of maintaining managerial control under a one-share one-vote system are high. As my proxy for control potential, I use industry dummy variables. Following Demsetz and Lehn, I expect certain industries, for example the media industry, to have greater control potential owing to managerial preferences. Since it would be very costly for managers of large firms and firms with high return volatility to have a large undiversified stake in their firm, I expect managers of these firms to be relatively more likely to adOpt a dual-class structure as a means of ensuring control while minimizing a manager’s economic exposure to the firm’s profit stream. Consistent with my control potential hypothesis, I find that firms in the media industry (e.g., publishing, broadcasting, motion pictures, etc.) are significantly more likely to have two classes of common stock. I also find that younger firms are more likely to have a dual-class structure. To the extent that managers of young firms are more likely to be founders who care about maintaining control, this can be viewed as additional evidence in support of the control motivation for selling two classes of stock. When I turn to the firm size and volatility measures, my results may be puzzling to some. My estimates suggest that the likelihood of having a dual-class structure is unrelated to firm size and negatively related to volatility. One potential explanation for this last result is that possible concerns about expropriation problems in highly volatile firms make it difficult to sell inferior voting common stock to outsiders. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 I discuss the related literature and explain where my paper fits in the context of these studies. In section 3 I discuss my data and sample selection criteria. In section 4 I report my main results, while section 5 concludes. 1.2 Existing Literature and Hypothesis Development 1.2.] Existing Literature Several existing studies have examined the issue of dual-class stocks. The majority of these studies examine the price differential between the superior voting shares and the inferior voting shares (e.g. Lease, McConnell, and Mikkelson (1983, 1984)). In general, the superior voting shares sell at a premium, and the time pattern and cross- sectional variation in these premia are consistent with votes being worth more when the likelihood of a control contest is high (Zingales (1994, 1995)).lc A separate set of studies have examined the announcement returns when a firm announces that it is adopting a dual class structure (e.g., Partch (1987), Jarrell and Poulsen (1988), Comett and Vetsuypens (1989), Chang and Mayers (1992), and Shum, Davidson and Glascock (1995)). These results are difficult to interpret, since announcement returns are likely to reflect both the value consequences of adopting a dual-class structure and information concerning the likelihood that a firm is acquired. Nevertheless, it is interesting that several of these studies indicate a positive market reaction, which suggests that there may be some benefits to the dual-class structure.2 In addition to these studies of stock price behavior, other studies have looked at the ownership composition of firms that have two classes of stock (e.g. DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1985) and Partch (1987)). As one would expect, these studies indicate that dual-class firms tend to have very concentrated inside ownership, and the percentage of votes held by management is typically significantly greater than the percentage of cash flows held by management. Two recent studies by Smart and Zutter (2001) and Grullon and Kanatas (2001) examine related issues by trying to understand the relationship between dual-class stock and other firm decisions. 3 1 Other studies explore the value of voting rights when a single investor holds a large voting block. Barclay and Holdemess (1989) find that in private negotiations large blocks of stock trade at a premium to the exchange price, and they argue that such premiums reflect the value of private benefits of control. 2 Theoretical work demonstrates that dual-class structures can either benefit or harm shareholders under different conditions. See, for example, Grossman and Hart (1988), Harris and Raviv (1988), Ruback (1988), Fischel (1987), Denis and Denis (1994) and Attari and Banerjee (1999). 3 See also Bohemer. Sanger and Varshney (1996) and Lehn, Netter and Poulson (1990). Many studies have also looked at dual-class common stock in countries outside the U84. In general, the results are similar to those of the US.5 1.2.2 Relationship to Existing Literature While these existing papers present many interesting findings, they do not answer the question as to why firms choose a dual-class structure in the first place. There is a common presumption that firms choose the dual-class structure to ensure managerial control. While this is almost surely true, it begs the question as to why some managers desire control and some do not. Presumably there are some economic tradeoffs that take place in the decision to adopt the dual-class structure. In particular, I would expect managers to weigh their desire for control with the penalties the market may assess to the inferior voting shares. This is very analogous to the issue raised by Demsetz and Lehn (1985) who ask whether patterns in managerial ownership are consistent with the various costs and benefits of control that ownership confers. In this paper I try to answer this question by identifying which firms have dual- class shares and which do not. I then run logit models that attempt to predict this decision. In addition to understanding the cross-sectional variation in the decision to adopt the dual-class structure, I am able to address two related and interesting issues. 4 Outside the US, dual-class firms are quite common in developed countries or regions such as Italy, Sweden, Switzerland, Denmark, Finland, Netherlands, Belgium, Canada, Hong Kong, Japan, United Kingdom and Israel and also emerging economies such as Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, South Korea, Pakistan, Singapore and China. 5 See, for example, Jog and Riding (1986), Robinson and White (1990), and Foster and Porter (1993) on Canadian firms; Ang and Megginson (1989) on British firms; Levy (1983) on Israel firms; Homer (1988), Kunz and Angel (1996), and Caramanolis, Gibson and Tuchschmid (1996) on Swiss firms; BergstrOm and First, I am able to assess for the first time the overall level of dual-class activity in the United States. This allows us to assess the economic importance of this type of corporate organization in the modern US. business environment. Second, my sampling procedures are designed to identify all instances of a dual-class structure — even cases where one of the two classes is not publicly traded. This distinguishes my study from previous studies, which generally restrict their attention to firms where both classes of common stock are listed on CRSP (e.g., Lease, McConnell, and Mikkelson (1983)). Thus, my study is more comprehensive and can for the first time, uncover the propensity for firms to sell one class of shares publicly and the other in the private markets. 1.2.3 Hypothesis Development In explaining the cross-sectional variation in the choice to adopt a dual—class structure, I must identify the potential costs and benefits of this structure. One potential benefit, initially identified by Demsetz and Lehn (1985), is that managers may experience a large utility payoff from being identified as the controlling party in certain high-profile firms, for example media firms and sports firms. This line of reasoning predicts that I should generally observe strong industry trends in the use of dual-class shares, and specifically I should observe many dual-class structures for firms in the media industry (there are insufficient sports firms in my sample to identify a sports firm effect). One way managers can ensure control under a one-share one-vote system is to purchase a majority of the shares. For large firms and firms with high volatility, the Rydqvist (1990), and Liljeblom and Rydquist (1992) on Swedish firms; Zingales (1994) and Nicodano ( 1998) on Italian firms; Taylor and Whittred (1998) on Australian firms. potential costs to the manager from pursuing such a policy in terms of the risk they bear could be prohibitive. One way to control the firm while minimizing the manager’s economic exposure is to adopt the dual-class structure. This suggests that, ceteris paribus, dual-class structures should be more likely in large firms and in firms with high levels of volatility. A final potential concern with dual-class shares is the valuation of the inferior voting shares. If managerial control has only benefits and no costs, the dual-class structure should not result in a penalty on the inferior voting shares. However, if managerial control results in potentially inefficient managerial behavior and/or expropriation of minority shareholders, this cost will enter into the decision to adopt the dual-class structure. To the extent that large firms and firms with high volatility are more subject to agency problems, these considerations would predict a negative relationship between the likelihood of a dual-class structure and firm size and volatility. 1.3 Data My goal is to identify all dual-class firms chosen by a large set of publicly traded firms. To accomplish this objective, I initially identify the set of all firms from 1990- 1999 listed on the Compustat tapes. After deleting limited partnerships, my sample contains 12,069 firms representing 71,679 firm years over the 1990-1999 period. For the resulting sample, I searched the company name field in the Compustat database and identified all firms with a share class indicator included in the name (e.g., AEL Industries -CL A.) This yields 503 US. firms representing 2,888 firm-years over the 1990-1999 period. Next, I turn to the CRSP tapes and identify all cases where the firm has two classes of common stock listed (e.g., AARON Rents Inc. has share classes A and B.) This procedure yields 666 firms representing 3480 firm years over 1990-1999. After merging the CRSP and Compustat databases (exact merging procedure available from the author), I found that there was substantial overlap in shares identified by the two procedures. After accounting for this duplication, my CRSP search procedure yields 183 new Compustat dual-class firms rcpresenting 868 firm-years. The above procedure is incomplete in that it relies exclusively on the CRSP and Compustat methods for reporting share classes and company names. For example, I suspected that in many cases a firm may have one class of shares that is traded on a major exchange and another that is not. It is not clear that the CRSP and Compustat procedure outlined above will identify all of these cases. To identify other instances of dual-class shares, I exploit the fact that CRSP typically reports a firm’s shares outstanding for a. single-class of common stock, while Compustat reports the number of shares outstanding for all classes of common stock added together. Thus, for cases where these two numbers differ significantly, it is likely that the firm has a dual-class structure. Using this line of reasoning, I identify every instance where these figures differ by more than 5%.6 I then searched through company financial statements, proxy statements, and the Dow Jones Interactive database to investigate whether the firm has multiple classes of common stock. Using the firm’s IO-K statement, I looked up detailed information on the share classes that are outstanding. Firms that are authorized to issue 6 My choice of a 5% rule is arbitrary, but probably rather conservative. As I report below, most firms 1 identify as dual-class by this procedure have a much larger difference in the shares outstanding figure between Compustat and CRSP. Note that if I do miss a few firms, given that they were not flagged by my two classes but only have one outstanding are classified as single-class firms. Only firms with outstanding shares with different voting rights are classified as dual-class firms. This procedure identifies 198 new dual-class firms representing 1022 firm years. The fact that I found a substantial number of new dual-class firms via this procedure suggests that procedures relying solely on CRSP and Compustat labeling are inadequate for identifying a comprehensive list of dual—class firms. Note that the median difference between the Compustat and CRSP share outstanding figures for the firms identified by this last procedure is 31.6%. Given my sampling procedures, I believe that I have the most comprehensive database of dual-class listed firms ever assembled. The above procedures yield a total sample of 884 dual class firms (4778 firm—years) out of 12069 firms (71679 firm-years). Thus, the overall rate of adopting the dual-class structure appears to be approximately 4,778/71,679 = 6.67%. To compare my sample to previous samples in the literature, note that Comett and Vetsuypens (1989) reported 271 dual class firms in 1962-1988 period identified by the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC) and Olrog and Rickhamre (1992) estimated 4 percent of 7200 US. firms were dual class firms. In Table 2 I report summary definitions for all of the variables used in the subsequent analysis. In Tables 3 and 4 I present univariate comparisons of some of the variables of interest for the single-class firms compared to the dual—class firms. I report these results both for the first year of the sample (1990) and the last year (1999). While most of these variables are fairly standard from the literature and are derived in a straightforward manner from the CRSP and Compustat tapes, a few variables are less 5% rule, it is almost surely the case that one of the classes has very few shares outstanding and, therefore. is likely to be economically unimportant. standard and should be discussed here. The variable Age is a proxy for the firm’s true age and is measured by identifying the first year that the firm’s stock has return data on the CRSP tape. I derive ownership data from the Compact Disclosure CDs. According to Anderson and Lee (1997), this is the most comprehensive database on inside ownership that is widely available. The variable Inpct is defined to equal the percentage of all common stock held by insiders (i.e., officers and directors). As the t-tests in Tables 3 and 4 indicate, dual class listed firms appear to differ significantly from the single-class listed firms on many dimensions including working capital, the market to book ratio, sales growth, liquidity, the P/E ratio, and some of the volatility measures. As I report in Table 5, the percentage of dual-class firms is particularly high in the publishing, media and motion picture industry, and is particularly low for utility and financial firms. 1.4 Analysis and results 1.4.] The Logit Model: Determinants of Dual-class Common Equity and their measurements I use a logit model to regress the binary dependent variable dual, which indicates if a firm has dual-class stock, on predictors described below. Of the possible general forces affecting issuing dual-class common equity, four are important enough to merit investigation. One of these, size of the firm is not surprising. The second is the age of the firm, which is related to the size of the firm. The third is the profit potential from more effective control of the firm. This is referred to as control potential. The fourth is 10 systematic regulation. Regulation imposes constraints on the scope and impact of shareholder decisions. The amenity potential of firms should be also included. In addition, financial ratios representing financial performance and market expectations should be considered as well. Size The size of firms that fit in the various product and input markets varies within and across industries. The larger the competitive viable size is, ceteris paribus, the larger is the firm’s capital sources and the greater is the value of fractional ownership. The higher price of a given fraction of the firm should reduce the degree to which ownership is concentrated. This constitutes a legitimate reason for owners to issue dual class shares. So it is logical to expect a nontrivial effect of firm size on the feasibility of issuing dual- class shares. Risk aversion should reinforce the effect. On the other hand larger firms are less likely to be a take—over targets so take-over defenses Such as dual-class common stock are needed less for large firms.7 I use assets, equity and their logarithms to proxy for size respectively. Age The age of the firm is closely related to firm size and ownership structure. A young firm is more likely to have a concentrated ownership structure or to maintain control by holding voting preferred classes of stock. As a firm grows, a larger amount of capital is required and it is harder for managers to maintain control. The use of dual-class stock as a defense against hostile takeovers becomes less important. Well-established 7 There were growing numbers of US. publicly traded firms issuing dual classes of common stock with differential voting rights in 19805. The increased adoption of dual classes in 19805 parallels a takeover wave and increased adoption of other antitakeover defense mechanism such as the issuance of ‘poison pills’ (Jarrell and Poulsen, 1988). This is also the case in Sweden (Liljeblom and Rydqvist, 1992). 11 firms would face investor pressure due to the issue of transparency and liquidity of the stock if they keep dual-class shares. A reverse relationship between age and the possibility to issue dual-class shares is expected. Control Potential Control potential is the gain achievable through more effective monitoring of managerial performance by a firm’s owners. Demsetz and Lehn (1985) believe that owners can influence the success of their firms and all outcomes are not completely random. Consequently, they assert that a firm’s control potential is directly associated with the noisiness of the environment in which it Operates. The noisier a firm’s environment, the greater the payoff to owners in maintaining tighter control. Hence, noisier environments should give rise to more a concentrated ownership structure. It is of interest to see if the uncertainty also affects the decision to issue dual-class shares. The three measures of instability examined here are (1) firm-specific risk, as measured by the standard error of the estimate calculated from fitting the market model, (2) the standard deviation of monthly stock market rates of return, and (3) the standard deviation of annual accounting profit rates. I favor firm-specific risk as the factor most strongly associated with the type of instability for which control is most useful. I include both a firm-specific risk measure and a firm total risk measure. Regulation Systematic regulation restricts the options available to owners thus reduces the control potential. Regulation also brings monitoring and disciplining of the management of the regulated firms. Regulation should reduce the likelihood of issuing dual-class l2 shares or maintaining a highly concentrated ownership structure. Thus financial and utility industries are expected to be less likely to issue dual class stocks. Amenity Potential There is nonpecuniary income associated with the provision of leadership and the ability to deploy resources to suit one’s personal preference. Two industries are well known examples for tighter control in order to indulge such personal preference. They are professional sports and mass media firms. To reach the consumption goals arising from the particular tastes of owners, it is necessary that owners are in a position to influence managerial decisions. Previous literature has documented concentrated ownership in these industries. The practice of dual-class shares might also be popular in these industries. Financial performance related to take-over possibilities Palepu (1986), and Comment and Schwert (1995) use several accounting and stock market performance measure to predict takeovers or the issuance of poison pills. They are sales growth rate, liquidity, debt ratio, and market to book value and price to earnings ratio. Since dual-class shares are a defense measure against takeovers, these ratios will be helpful in explaining the issuance of dual-class shares. 1.4.2 Results of Logit Analysis The logit regression is covers the years from 1990 to 1999. The basic results are reported in Table 6-9. 13 Surprisingly, the size proxy (assets) generally is not statistically significant when assets, age, industry dummies and the standard deviation of monthly return are used as predictors. When the financial ratios such as sales growth, liquidity, debt ratio, market to book ratio and P/E ratio are included in the regressions, assets becomes statistically significant and the sign is negative. However, this is mainly because many small firms are dropped because of missing data on financial ratios the year before or the average of 4 years before. The size of the firms after the small firms are dropped is comparable to previous studies, and a similar result is generated: the assets factor is statistically significant and having large assets reduces the probability of having dual-class shares, ceteris paribus. It does not affect the significance of assets whether age is included in the regression or not. The results are similar using the logarithm of assets I also use equity, the market value of equity to replace assets in the regression. Equity is statistically significant and the sign is negative whether the financial ratios are included or not (the regressions are not reported here). The market value of equity might be a better measure in the sense that it is directly related to the size of wealth to maintain certain ownership levels. Age of the firm is statistically significant and the sign is negative. However, it becomes only marginally significant or not significant when the five financial ratios are included in the regressions. The negative sign shows the young and immature firms are more likely to have dual-class shares. The industry effect is clear. The dummy publish is significant and positive in all regressions, broadcast is statistically significant and positive in most regressions, mo- picture is significant and positive in all regressions. This is consistent with the notion that 14 tighter control is required to achieve the amenity potential. Another reason is that personal preference is important in such industries in which it is hard to predict outcome from managerial decisions. Managers are vulnerable and need tighter control and higher ownership to protect them. The utility dummy is statistically significant and negative in all regressions. The finance dummy is statistically significant and negative in most regressions. This indicates the likelihood for systematically regulated industries to have dual-class shares is less than that for other firms. It is likely that utility firms are affected more by regulation than are financial firms. Firm-specific risk is statistically significant in all the years except 1996 and negatively related to issuing dual-class shares. The result is the same if another measure of instability, total risk, is used in place of firm-specific risk. One would think this result is different from what is expected from the literature on ownership concentration. Here, however, I study the decision to have dual-class shares which is not equivalent to ownership concentration. Investors usually would prefer transparency in managerial decisions and the owner-management relationship. There is evidence that investors regard dual-class firms as an indicator of low levels of transparency. Firms with high instability would care more about transparency because investors require more transparency for such volatile stocks. The investors also often believe dual-class firms have much lower liquidity. Firms with high instability would also like to have high stock liquidity because investors require these firms to have high liquidity. A firm with high instability would prefer not to have dual-class shares although it tends to have a higher ownership concentration on average. In addition to linearly estimating the probability to 15 have dual-class shares, I also estimate this relationship in nonlinear form by adding the square of the instability measure. The squared value of the variables are positively related to probability to have dual-class shares, indicating at lower values of these variables the increase in the probability associated with given a decrease in instability diminishes. The five financial ratios, both value of the year before and the average of 4 years before, are not statistically significant in general. The merger and acquisition market in the 19905 was very different from that in the 19805. Hence, dual-class shares may now be less important as a defense against a takeover. Insider ownership is closely related to dual-class shares. When insider ownership is included in the regression, it is statistically significant and positive as expected. High insider ownership increases the probability of having dual-class shares. I also regress insider ownership on dual, size, age, industry dummies and instability measures (not reported here). As expected, dual is statistically significant and positive, size is statistical significant and negative, age is statistical significant and negative, the utility dummy is statistically significant and negative, m-picture dummy is statistically significant and positive. However, both the publish and broadcast dummies are not statistically significant. The instability measure is statistically significant and positive which is consistent with the control potential hypothesis. 1.5 Conclusion In this paper I examine the propensity of firms to issue two classes of common stock. I hypothesize that dual-class structures should be more common in situations 16 where a firm’s control potential is high. In addition, if the dual-class decision is driven by managerial risk aversion and the fear of having a large undiversified economic stake in a firm, I expect the dual—class structure to be more likely in large firms and firms with high levels of volatility. Conversely, if agency problems are more severe in large and/or risky firms, the dual-class structure may be relatively less likely in these firms owing to a large penalty assessed by the outside market to the inferior voting shares. To investigate these issues I identify the dual-class status of all Compustat listed firms over the 1990-1999 time period. I find that previous procedures to identify dual- class firms are biased towards under-reporting the frequency of the dual-class structure, and my sample reveals that approximately 6.67% of US. firms have adopted a dual class structure. Consistent with my control potential hypothesis, in my logit models I find that firms in the media industry (e.g., publishing, broadcasting, motion pictures, etc.) are significantly more likely to have two classes of common stock. I also find that younger firms are more likely to have a dual-class structure. To the extent that managers of young firms are more likely to be founders who care about maintaining control, this can be viewed as additional evidence in support of the control motivation for selling two classes of stock. When I turn to the firm size and volatility measures my logit estimates suggest that the likelihood of having a dual-class structure is unrelated to firm size and negatively related to volatility. Thus, the diversification motivation for adopting the dual-class structure does not appear consistent with my data. However, the data do appear highly consistent with the hypothesis that agency problems or concerns about expropriation in 17 highly volatile firms makes it difficult to sell inferior voting common stock to outsiders in these environments. 18 CHAPTER 2 Dual-Class Stock, Firm Value, and Performance 2.1 Introduction One way to solve the agency problem is via the use of incentive compensation and managerial ownership. Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988) demonstrate empirically that managerial ownership may raise firm value by solving agency problems. However, their analysis indicates that there may be both costs and benefits to high managerial ownership. While high ownership may enhance a manager’s incentive to act in shareholders interests, it may also entrench managers by giving them the ability to insulate themselves from outSide market forces (e. g., unwanted acquisition attempts). A dual class structure is an interesting way to keep control of the firm. There have been mixed arguments and evidence in the finance literature on whether dual class stocks are value enhancing or value decreasing. Harris and Raviv (1988), and Grossman and Hart (1988) show that one share one vote is optimal although dual class stock can benefit the shareholder under certain conditions in takeovers. On the other hand, Attari and Banerjee (1999) argue that if the firm requires outside equity financing to undertake the project, it will find separation of the vote and dividend claim optimal in cases. The separation increases the manager’s willingness to undertake all positive NPV projects. Managers in single class firm will give up some positive NPV projects requiring managers to issue equity to outsiders because they are 19 worried about losing control of the firm and being replace by outsiders. DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1985) argue that a dual class structure can encourage managers to invest in firm-specific human capital which adds value to the firm. In this paper I conduct an analysis of the value of firms that choose to adopt a dual-class share structure. While many existing studies have looked at the share price levels and behavior of dual-class stocks, no study has convincingly examined the relationship between dual class stock and firm value. No study has carefully examined the effect of ownership of cashflow rights and ownership of voting rights separately. Using a comprehensive sample of almost all publicly traded firms in the US. in 1995, I conduct an analysis that describes whether dual class firms under perform and the effect of dual class stock on firm value. My analysis also shows the relation between firm value and ownership of cashflow rights and voting rights separately. Following the work of Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988), I hypothesize that managers in dual class firms can maintain control without worrying about being replaced and having less cash flow rights than voting rights, thus leading to sluggish management and unwise investment. Dual class structure makes it more likely that an inefficient manager will keep control than in one share/one vote. One share/one vote aligns the interests of managers more closely with shareholders. Thus I expect a lower Tobin’s Q for a dual class firms compared with its industry peers. On the other hand, according to the shareholder interest hypothesis, managers may want some form of takeover defense for surplus-protection and surplus-extraction which is in the interest of target shareholders. Perhaps a more common occurrence is that a dual class structure creates stability that can be beneficial. According to the under- 20 investment hypothesis developed by Attari and Banerjee (1999), the dual class structure mitigates the under-investment problem when managers have to issue equity to finance new projects. Thus, I expect a higher or similar Tobin’s Q for a dual class firm compared with its industry peers if the shareholder interest hypothesis is true. Overall, I find that dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than their peers of sirrrilar size in the same industry. However dual class firms that have both classes traded publicly have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms and Tobin’s Q increases as insider ownership of cash flow rights rises and declines as insider ownership of voting rights rises in the sub sample of dual class firms that have both classes traded and single class firms. On the other hand, dual class firms that have one class stock traded publicly do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firm. The media industries are special in that the control potential is large as shown in my first essay. I find within media industries, dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firm while within non- media industries dual class firms have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms. In media industries, dual class firms pay less dividends than single class firms, the dividend payouts increases as insider ownership of cash flow rights rises and declines as insiders ownership of voting rights rises — there is no such relation in the non-media industries. There is no evidence that dual class firms underperform single class peers on certain performance measures, such as Market-to-book equity ratio and Price/Earnings ratio. There is some evidence that dual class firms underperform single class peers on some other performance measures, such as ROA, EBIT, and operating cash flow. On these measures, firm performance rises with insider ownership of cash flow rights and decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 I discuss the related literature and explain where my paper fits in the context of these studies. In section 3 I discuss my data and sample selection criteria. In section 4 I report my main results, while section 5 concludes. 2.2 Existing Literature and Hypothesis Development 2.2.] Existing Literature Many studies find that superior voting shares sell at a premium. They also examine the time pattern and cross-sectional variation in price differential between the superior voting shares and the inferior voting shares (e.g. Lease, McConnell, and Mikkelson (1983, 1984)). In general this premium is consistent with votes being worth more when the likelihood of a control contest is high (Zingales (1994, 1995)) Several existing studies have examined the issuance of dual-class stock. Many authors study the wealth effect of dual class recapitalization in attempt to find out the impact of a dual class structure on firm value. Partch (1987) finds nonnegative abnormal returns on the announcement of a recapitalization. Jarrel and Poulsen (1988) find significant negative returns while Comett and Vetsuypen (1989) report positive abnormal returnss. These results are inconclusive since announcement returns are likely to reflect both the value consequences of adopting a dual-class structure and information 22 concerning the likelihood that a firm is acquired. Nevertheless, it is interesting that several of these studies indicate a positive market reaction, which is suggestive that there may be some benefits to the dual-class structure. In addition to these studies of stock price behavior, other studies have looked at the ownership composition of firms that have two classes of stock (e.g. DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1985), Partch (1987)). As one would expect, these studies indicate that dual- class firms tend to have very concentrated inside ownership, and the percentage of votes held by management is typically significantly greater than the percentage of cash flows held by management. 2.2.2 Relationship to Existing Literature While these existing papers present many interesting findings, they do not answer the question as to whether a dual class structure destroys or enhances firm value and performance. There is a well-known hypothesis that managerial control is inefficient since it leads to entrenchment. However, a firm’s decision to have dual class stock may not be just to the interest of insiders. Presumably there are some economic tradeoffs that take place in the decision to adopt the dual-class structure. In particular, I would expect there to be a benefit to outsiders and to the firm as a whole to have dual class stock, thus firm value will not simply decline because of manageerial entrenchment. In this paper I try to answer this question by identifying the separation of cash flow rights and voting rights of dual class firms. I then match dual class firms with their industry peers to compare firm value and performance. I run regressions to examine the 8 Also see Chang and Mayers (1992) and Shum. Davidson and Glascock (1995). 23 cross sectional variation of firm value and performance with different degrees of separation of cash flow rights and voting rights. In addition to understanding the relation between firm value and dual class stocks, I am able to address related interesting issues. I am able to assess for the first time the overall level of insider ownership in dual classes and the degree of the separation of cash flow rights and voting rights of dual class firms in the United States. This allows me to assess the economic importance of this type of corporate control in the modern US. business environment. 2.2.3 Hypothesis Development In explaining the valuation and performance of the dual-class firms compared with single class firms, I must identify the potential costs and benefits of this structure. In general there is trade off between the cost and the benefits. According to Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988), the managerial entrenchment hypothesis claims that managers in dual class firms can maintain control without worrying about being replaced, thus leading to sluggish management and unwise investment. The dual class structure protects inefficient incumbent managers from a control contest. A dual class structure makes it more likely that an inefficient manager will keep control than in one share/one vote. One share/one vote aligns the interest of managers more closely with shareholders. If there is no benefit of control, there is substantial cost of dual class shares because outside investors would pay more for the equity issued by a single-class firm than for the equity issued by a dual-class firm. Thus, the managerial entrenchment hypothesis predicts a lower Tobin’s Q for a dual class firm 24 compared with its industry peers. Dual class firms could also be outperformed by single class firms in other operating performance measures. The managerial entrenchment hypothesis also predicts that Tobin’s Q declines with insider ownership of voting rights while increases with insider cashflow rights. On the other hand, according to the shareholder interest hypothesis, managers may want some form of takeover defense for surplus-protection and surplus-extraction which is in the interest of target shareholders. Perhaps more important, a dual class structure creates stability which can be beneficial. First, according to the underinvestment hypothesis developed by Attari and Banerjee (1999), the dual class structure mitigates the under-investment problem when managers have to issue equity to finance new projects. Managers in a single class firm will give up the positive NPV projects because the equity issue will dilute their equity ownership thus gradually reducing their control. However, if a firm issues a restricted voting class of equity to outside investors then managers can undertake all positive NPV projects without dilution of voting control. Second, DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1985), Fischel (1987) and Denis and Denis (1994) argue that the reduced threat of displacement provides managers with incentives to invest in firm-specific human capital. Thus, the shareholder interest hypothesis predicts a higher or similar Tobin’s Q for a dual class firm compared with its industry peers. Dual class firms also should not be outperformed by single class firms in other Operating performance measures. Unlike the managerial entrenchment hypothesis, the shareholder interest hypothesis does not predict that Tobin’s Q declines with insider ownership of voting rights while increases with insider cashflow rights. 25 2.3 Data My goal is to identify all dual—class firms and their ownership chosen from a large 9. To accomplish this objective, I initially identify the set of set of publicly traded firms all firms from 1990-1999 listed on the Compustat tapes. For the resulting sample, I search the company name field in the Compustat database and identify all firms with a share class indicator included in the name (e.g., AEL Industries —CL A.) Next, I turn to the CRSP tapes and identify all cases where the firm has two classes of common stock listed (e.g., AARON Rents Inc. has share classes of A and B.) The above procedure is incomplete in that it relies exclusively on the CRSP and Compustat methods for reporting share classes and company names. It is not clear that the CRSP and Compustat procedure outlined above will identify all of these cases. To identify other instances of dual-class shares, I exploit the fact that CRSP typically reports a firm’s shares outstanding for a single-class of common stock, while Compustat reports the number of shares outstanding for all classes of common stock added together. I identify every instance where these shares figures differ by more than 5%.'0 I then search through company financial statements, proxy statements, and the Dow Jones Interactive database to investigate whether the firm has multiple classes of common stock. The above procedures yield a total sample of 391 dual class firms out of 8286 firms in year 1995. 9 See more details in the first essay. '0 My choice of a 5% rule is arbitrary, but probably rather conservative. A51 report below, most firms 1 identify as dual-class by this procedure have a much larger difference in the shares outstanding figure between Compustat and CRSP. Note that if I do miss a few firms, given that they were not flagged by my 5% rule, it is almost surely the case that one of the classes has very few shares outstanding and. therefore, is likely to be economically unimportant. 26 Given my sampling procedure, I believe that I have the most comprehensive database of dual-class listed firms ever assembled. I then search through the proxy statements, 10K filings, annual reports and Dow Jones Interactive to identify the number of votes per share for each class, number of shares outstanding for each class, the level of insider ownership, and CEO ownership and block holdings in each class of dual class firms in 1995. Insider ownership includes ownership of firm executives and board directors. Block holdings refers to any block of ownership more than 5% of the class. I use ownership data from Compact Disclosure for insider ownership of single class firm in 1995. According to Anderson and Lee (1997), this is the most comprehensive database on inside ownership that is widely available. I also identify whether the dual class firm trade both classes publicly or only trade one class publicly. The exchanges where the shares traded are also recorded. In Table 1 I report summary definitions of all the variables I use in the subsequent analysis. In Table 2 I present univariate comparisons of some of the variables of interest for the single-class firms compared to the dual-class firms. I report these results the year 1995. While most of these variables are fairly standard from the literature and are derived in a straightforward manner from the CRSP and Compustat tapes, a few variables are less standard and should be discussed here. Ownsuper is the insider ownership in the superior voting class and Owninfer is the insider ownership in the inferior voting shares. Sharesuper is the number of shares outstanding in superior voting class and Shareinfer is the number of shares outstanding in the inferior voting class. Votesuper is the votes per share for the superior voting class and Voteinfer is the votes per share for the inferior voting class. The Voting Rights is insider ownership of voting rights of common stocks. 27 The insiders’ voting rights are measured as a percentage of the total number of outstanding votes. Ownsmger’“Sharesuper*Votesrmer+Owninfer*Shareinfer*Voteinfer VotingRights = Sharesuper*Votesuper+Shareinfer*Voteinfer The Cashflow rights is insider ownership of common stocks based on monetary value and I calculate the insiders’ implied common stock cash interest as the weighted average of their percentage holdings in the superior and inferior voting classes: CashflowRights = Ownsuper*Shagsuper+0wninfer*Shareinfer Sharesuper+Shareinfer The variable SEPARATION is the separation index of ownership of voting rights and cashflow rights and SEPARATION = Voting Rights/Cashflow Rights. STDF is the standard error of the monthly stock market rates of return in the previous four years estimated from a market model in which the firm’s monthly return in the previous four years is regressed on the average monthly return on a value-weighted market portfolio. The variable Age is a proxy for the firm’s true age and is measured by identifying the first year that the firm’s stock has return data on the CRSP tape. As the t-tests in Table 2 indicate, dual class listed firms appear to differ significantly from the single-class listed firms on many dimensions including the market- to-book equity ratio, sales growth, liquidity, the P/E ratio, and some of the measures of volatility. As I report in Table 3 and also in the first essay, the percentage of dual-class firms is particularly high in the publishing, broadcasting and motion picture industry, and it is particularly low for utilities and financial firms. 28 2.4 Analysis and Results 2.4.] The Separation of cash flow rights and voting rights Table 4A document insider ownership in each of the two classes. ( The table does not include the firms with more than two classes of common stocks.) Table 4B reports the insiders’ voting rights and cash flow rights from common stocks. Insiders include executive officers and board directors. Ownership includes shares owned by officers and directors, trusts for their benefactors and foundations or corporations they control. The level of insider ownership in each class is hand collected from proxy statements, 10K filings and annual reports. Insiders in dual class firms hold a substantially higher percentage of the stock with more votes than of the stocks with fewer votes. In Table 4A the mean insider ownership in the superior voting class is 63.73% and the mean insider ownership in the inferior voting class is 21.65%. The t-statistic for equal means is 20.81. Insider ownership in the superior voting shares is substantially greater than that of inferior voting shares. The insiders hold a median of 71.23% in the superior voting class while they hold a median of 14.60% in the inferior class. The Wilcox sign-rank test for equal medians is 13.51. Both the mean insider ownership-and median insider ownership are significantly higher in the superior voting class than in the inferior voting class. In Table 4.B., the insiders hold a mean of 34.65% of cash flow rights from common stock and a mean of 54.80% of voting rights. The t-statistic for equal means is 17.92. The insiders hold a median of 32.25% of cash flow rights from common stock and a median of 60.58% of 29 voting rights. The Wilcox sign-rank test for equal medians is 12.59. Both the mean and median insider cash flow rights are significantly lower than those of voting rights. The mean SEPARATION Index is 1.875 and the median SEPARATION Index is 1.500. Table 4C shows the holdings of CEOs in the two classes. The mean CEO ownership in the superior voting class is 34.75% and the mean CEOs’ ownership in the inferior voting class is 9.94%. The t-statistic is 13.53. The CEOs hold a median of 25.05% in the superior voting class while they only hold a median of 2.2% in the inferior class. The Wilcox sign-rank test is 11.28. Both mean CEO ownership and median CEO ownership are significantly higher in the superior voting class than in the inferior voting class. Table 4F shows the holdings of the largest block shareholder in the two classes. The mean largest blockholder’s ownership in the superior voting class is 60.13% and the mean largest blockholder’s ownership in the inferior voting class is 27.25%. The largest blockholder holds a median of 56.67% in the superior voting class while they only hold a median of 19.29% in the inferior class. The voting rights and cash rights of insiders in firms in the media industry are compared with those in non-media industries in Table 4D. Insiders hold similar mean and median ownership of voting rights and cash flow rights in media industries and non- media industries. There is no significant difference found. The separation of voting rights and cash flow rights are similar across industries with different likelihood to issue dual class stock (or different control potential.) Table 4B reports the voting rights and cash flow rights in firms that have both classes publicly traded and have only one class traded publicly. In both sub-samples the insiders in dual class firms hold substantially higher levels of ownership of voting rights 30 compared to cashflow rights. The insiders in firms with one class traded publicly have a mean ownership of voting rights of 57.0%, significantly higher than their mean ownership of cashflow rights of 34.3%. The insiders in firms with one class traded publicly have a median ownership of voting rights of 63.8%, significantly higher than their median ownership of cashflow rights of 31.4%. The insiders in firms with both classes publicly traded have a mean ownership of voting rights of 49.2%, significantly higher than their mean ownership of cashflow rights of 33.0%. The insiders in firms with both classes traded publicly have a median ownership of voting rights of 52.2%, significantly higher than their median ownership of cashflow rights of 32.6%. A more interesting issue is whether dual class firms with both classes traded publicly have less separation of voting rights and cash flow rights since the voting preferred stocks can be purchased in the market by outsiders. The insiders in firms with one class traded publicly have a mean ownership of voting rights of 57.0%, significantly higher than a mean of 49.2% for firms with both classes traded publicly, t-statistic = 1.963. The insiders in firms with one class publicly traded have a median ownership of voting rights of 63.8%, significantly higher than a median of 52.2% for firms with both classes traded publicly, Wilcox sign-rank test = 1.963. Insiders in the two types of dual class firms have about same mean and median ownership of cash flow rights. The insiders in firms with one class traded publicly have a mean ownership of cashflow rights of 34.3% and a median of 31.4%. The insiders in firms with both classes traded publicly have a mean ownership of cashflow rights of 33.0% and a median of 32.6%. By letting both classes publicly trade the dual class firms do have a little less control. However, these dual class firms still hold a median of 52.2% voting rights compared to a median of 31 32.58% of cash flow rights. Letting the superior voting shares trade publicly does not significantly reduce insider control of the firm. Insiders still hold a large amount of those superior voting shares, although they appear to sell out a little portion. 2.4.2 Matching of dual class firms with single class firms My major goal is to compare the value and performance of dual class firms with single class firms. It is well established that corporate governance affects firm value. Gompers, Ishii and Metrick (2001) show corporate governance is highly correlated with firm value and stock returns. The authors excluded dual class firms from their sample. In this section I use a matching approach to study whether the variation in a firm’s decision to issue dual class stock is related to cross sectional differences in firm value and performance. As is well known, industry and size are the majOr factors in firm value and performance. I match each dual class firm with a firm closest in size (total assets) in the same industry. I use the two-digit sic code as the proxy for industry. Table 5 documents the dual class firms’ value and performance measure and those of matching firms. My valuation measure is Tobin’s Q, which has been used routinely for this purpose in corporate governance studies. I follow Kaplan and Zingales (1997) and compute Q as the market value of assets divided by the book value of assets, where the market value of assets is computed as book value of assets plus the market value of common stock less the sum of the book value of common stock and balance sheet deferred taxes. Perfect and Wiles (1994) and Chung and Pruitt (1994) show that the improvements obtained from a more involved computation of Q are fairly limited. 32 I also include market-to-book equity ratio in the comparison. Operating performance measures include the Price/Earning ratio, Return on assets, cash flow (Operating Cash Flow/Total Assets), EBIT (EBIT/Total Assets), and the Dividend Ratio (Cash Dividends/Total Equity). Table 5 shows that overall there is no strong significant difference between dual class firms’ value and performance and those of matching single class firms, although dual class firm have a lower median Tobin’s Q in the next year (1996) and a lower Market-to-Book equity ratio than single class matching firms. The dual class firms perform as well as single class firms. This is not consistent with the managerial entrenchment hypothesis. Insiders do not use a dual class structure to entrench inefficient management. Table 6A reports the performance of the sub-sample of dual class firms that have both classes publicly traded compared to the matching firms. Table 6B reports the performance of the sub-sample of dual class firms that have only one class traded publicly compared with the matching firms. Surprisingly, I find that dual class firms with both classes traded publicly actually under-perform their single-class peers and dual class firms that have only one class traded perform as well as their single-class peers. Dual class firms with both classes traded have a mean Tobin’s Q of 1.454. This is significantly lower than the matching firms’ mean of 1.813 (t statistics: -1.650). Dual class firms with both classes traded have a median Tobin’s Q of 1.146 significant lower than matching firms’ median of 1.396 (statistically significant at 1% level). Dual class firms with both classes traded publicly also have a significantly lower median Tobin’s q in the next year ( 1996). Besides Tobin’s q, dual class firms with both classes traded publicly also have a 33 significantly lower median Market-to-Book equity ratio, a significantly lower median investment level and a significantly lower mean dividend payout ratio. As shown in the previous section, dual class firms with both classes traded publicly have a lower degree of separation of voting rights and cash flow rights than dual class firms that have only one class traded publicly. If the managerial entrenchment hypothesis were true, we would expect dual class firms that have both classes traded publicly to perform better than dual—class firms that have only one class traded relative to their matching single class firms. My results show that the higher degree of separation of ownership of voting rights and cashflow rights does not destroy firm value. This is not consistent with the managerial entrenchment hypothesis or there is something more than entrenchment. One potential benefit, initially identified by Demsetz and Lehn (1985), is that managers may experience a large utility payoff from controlling firms with high control potential or amenity potential and/or for being identified as the controlling party in certain high-profile firms, for example media firms and sports firms. This line of reasoning predicts that I should generally observe strong industry trends in the use of dual-class shares, and specifically I should observe many dual-class structures for firms in the media industry. My findings in the first essay are consistent with these predictions. If control is also beneficial to outside shareholders, a further prediction is that dual class firms in media industries should not have a lower value than single class firms while dual class firms in other industries may have a lower value. Table 7A reports the performance of the sub-sample of dual class firms in media industries, compared with the matching firms. Table 7B reports the performance of the sub-sample of dual class firms in non- 34 media industries compared with the matching firms. Media industries includes SIC code from 2700 to 2799 (publishing), from 4800 to 4899 (broadcasting) and 7800 to 7899 (motion pictures). All other industries (SIC code from 0100 to 9999) are defined as non- media industries. 1 find that dual class firms in media industries actually do not under- perform their single-class peers. There is some evidence that dual class firms in non- media industries do not perform as well as their single-class peers. Dual class firms in non-media industries have a next-year median Tobin’s Q of 1.356. This is statistically significantly lower than matching firms’ median of 1.447. Dual class firms in non-media industries do not have Price-Earning ratios significantly different from their single class peers. Dual class firms in the media industries have a median Price-Eaming ratio of 17.75. This is significantly higher than the matching firms’ median of 0 (statistically significant at the 5% level). Dual class firms in the media industries have a mean Price- Eamings ratio of 38.06. This is significantly higher than matching firms’ mean of 13.83 (t-statistic = 1.819). Dual class firms in media industries also have a significantly higher mean and median a-year-forward Price-Eaming ratio than matching firms while non- media dual class firms do not. Dual class firms in media industries have a significantly higher mean EBIT/Total Assets ratio than matching firms while dual class firms in non- media industries do not have an EBIT/Total Assets ratio significantly different from the matching firms. Dual class firms in media industries also have a significantly higher mean Operating Cashflow/Assets ratio in the following year (1996) than matching firms while dual class firms in non-media industries do not have 3 Operating Cashflow/Assets ratio significantly different from the matching firms. 35 If the managerial entrenchment hypothesis were true, we would expect that dual class firms in both media industries and non-media industries under-perform their matching single class counterparts. My results show that the dual class firms in media industries do not under—perform the matching single class firms while the dual class firms in non-media industries somewhat under-perform their peers. This is not consistent with the managerial entrenchment hypothesis. The control obtained by the dual class structure is not harmful to firm value in industries where the control potential is high. 2.4.3 Cross sectional regression of Tobin ’s Q 2.4.3.1 Empirical regression models I use several regression models to study the effect of a dual class structure and separation of voting rights and cash flow rights on firm value. I first estimate Q=a+bDUAL+cW+e (1) where DUAL is a dummy variable equal to 1 for dual class firms and 0 for single class firms. W, is a vector of firm characteristics. As elements of Wi, I follow Gompers, et al., (2001) and Shin and Stulz (2000) and use the log of the book value of assets, the log of firm age and a dummy variable for each of the four~digit SIC codes. The book value of assets, age, and two-digit SIC code are also used as a robustness check. It is obvious that industry, size, and age are critical control variables in regression of Q. My empirical results below show that stock volatility is also an important control variable. 36 Regression with the dummy variable DUAL can give an estimate of the effect of a dual class structure on firm value. More specifically I can estimate the effect of separation of voting rights and cash flow rights on Q. So I estimate Q=a+bDUAL+cCASH+dW+e (2) and Q=a+bVOTE+cCASH+dW+e (3) and Q=a+bSEPARATION+CW+e (4) Where CASH is the cash flow rights of insiders and VOTE is the voting rights of insiders. Separation index equals VOTE divided by CASH. A piecewise regression may be desirable as in Morck, Shelifer and Vishny (1988). Q may not be a monotonic function of insider ownership of voting rights and cash flow rights, but a piece wise function of insider ownership. I use the following variable to estimate and report my piece wise linear regressions: Vote.0tolO = insider ownership of voting rights if insiders ownership < 0.10 =O.lO if insiders ownership of voting rights if insiders ownership 2 O. 10 Vote.0VERlO= 0 if insider ownership < 0.10 = insider ownership of voting rights minus .10 if insider ownership of voting rights 2 0.10 Cash.0to75 = insider ownership of cash flow rights if insider ownership of cash flow rights < 0.75 = 0.75 if insider ownership of cash flow rights if insider ownership of cash flow rights 2 0.75 37 Cash.OVER75= 0 if insider ownership of cash flow rights < 0.75 = insider ownership of cash flow rights minus .75 if insider ownership of cash flow rights 2 0.75 The theoretical justification for the piecewise regressions and these particular turning points is not very strong. Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988) use 5% and 25% as turning points for board ownership which combines ownership of voting rights and cash flow rights. My analysis is different from Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988) in that a dual class structure allows me to separate the insider ownership of voting rights from the insider ownership of cash flow rights. It is not well justified that there is a 5% and 25% turning point for insider ownership of cash flow rights. I use a turning point of 75% for ownership of cash flow rights in attempt to describe the diminishing incentives from the ownership of cash flow rights when the ownership is high enough. I use 10% as a turning point for ownership of voting rights since an ownership of voting rights less than 10% does not confer significant power while an ownership of voting rights higher than 10% would give insiders significant power. For regressions using other turning points (not reported here) I define the variables analogously. The results are either similar or hard to justify. I estimate cross sections of (1) - (4) using data of 1995. I also use this procedure when studying other performance measures in the next a couple of sections. 1 hand collect the 1995 ownership data of dual class firms from proxy statements, 10 K filings, and annual reports. The single class firms’ ownership data is from Compact Disclosure which is very reliable for single class firms according to Anderson and Scott (1997). 38 2.4.3.2 Regression of fill] sample Table 7 summarizes the regression results based on the above regression models for the full sample. All but one regression reports no statistically significant relationship between DUAL dummy (equals one if a dual class firm, zero otherwise) and Q, between insider ownership of voting rights and Q or between voting rights-cashflow rights SEPERATION Index and Q. Hence, there is no convincing evidence that a dual class structure diminishes firm value. This is not consistent with the managerial entrenchment hypothesis. I also do a robustness check. To deal with the possibility that a variety of factors can jointly affect board ownership and Q, and thus induce a spurious correlation between them, I control for additional variables in the regression. Besides size, age, and industry effect, R&D expenditure and advertising expenditure may be measures of intangible assets that affect Q. Consequently, I include RD/ASSETS (R&D Expenses divided by Total Assets) and ADV/ASSETS (Advertising Expenses divided by Total Assets) in the regression. The results are similar if I exclude financial firms with SIC code in the range of 6000-6999 and utility firms with SIC code in the range of 4900-4999, which is the practice in many corporate finance studies. I regress on a subsample of the larger firms, the results, not reported here, are similar to Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988). Their sample is composed of Standard & Poor 500 firms which are the largest firms. So my full sample results are different from their results because my sample contains all the smaller firms in Compustat. 39 2.4.3.3 Dual class firms with both classes traded vs. dual class firms with only one class traded Table 9 summarizes the results for regressions of the subsample with dual class firms that have both classes traded publicly and the dual class firms that have one class traded publicly. I also include a stock volatility measure, RD/ASSETS and/or ADV/ASSETS in the regression. The results are similar if I exclude financial firms with SIC code in the range of 6000-6999 and utility firms with SIC code in the range of 4900- 4999. The first couple of columns show that dual class firms with both classes traded publicly have a lower q value. In the third and fourth column, the DUAL dummy (1 if dual class firms, 0 otherwise) is significantly negative. More striking, given the regression equation (3), the sixth column show that the insider ownership of voting rights is negatively related to Q, while the insider ownership of cashflow rights is positively related to Q. For a dual—class firm that has both classes traded publicly, everything else held constant, a 10 percentage point increase in inside ownership of cash flow rights will increase Tobin’s Q by 0.73, while a 10 percentage point increase in inside ownership of voting rights will decrease Tobin’s Q by .58. The coefficients are statistically and economically significant. Table 9 also shows that dual class firms with one class traded publicly do not have a lower Tobin’s Q. There is an interesting question as to why dual class firms with both classes traded publicly are valued lower. The difference between the two types of dual class firms is that the firms that have both classes traded publicly, insiders can sell their superior voting shares in the market. Insiders in the firms with one class traded 40 publicly cannot sell their shares easily. As these firms’ proxy statements show, the shares of the privately held class usually are not transferable or will be converted to shares of a publicly traded class upon transfer, or are transferable upon permission of the board. Since they may not be able to bail out by selling shares if the firms are in financial trouble, the insiders in these firms have a commitment to the success of the firm. So there is a signal of interest alignment by holding a class of stocks that cannot be traded publicly. As is well known, there is a difference between prices of the two classes of stock when both are traded. When dual class firms have both classes traded publicly, the shares with more votes usually are traded at a higher price than the shares with fewer votes. The relative premium investors are willing to pay for additional votes is called a voting premium. As documented by Zingales (1995), the voting premium on the voting- preferred class of stock on average is 10.5% (the median is 3%). However, there are other differences between the two classes that affect the relative price of shares between the two classes, such as difference in dividends, conversion rights and liquidity. Following Zingales (1995), the nominal voting premium is given by: Wu = Bo + 5101mm +BzDIVrr + BsCONVrr + B4SIZEir + BSLIQUIDITYR + 8n (5) where VP is the nominal voting premium. ((1)/1t) proxies for the voting power and B] represents the real voting premium. DIV is a dummy variable equals one for those firms in which inferior voting shares received a larger dividend. CONV is a dummy variable that takes a value of one for firms in which the superior voting shares are convertible into inferior voting shares at the holder’s will. SIZE is the total market capitalization of stock. LIQUIDITY is the relative stock liquidity difference of the two classes. If equation (6) 41 were used to price the superior voting shares not traded publicly, I would expect a negative or non-positive nominal premium. Because there is a large liquidity premium for voting inferior shares over voting superior shares if the liquidity of shares that cannot be transferred easily is assumed to be close to zero. Therefore, insiders in dual class firms with one class traded publicly do sacrifice the value of shares they hold for keep the voting control. This also leads me to suspect that the motivation for dual class firms to let the superior voting shares trade publicly is to increase the liquidity of the shares insiders previously held privately thus increasing the value of their holdings and diversifying the risk they face. 2.4.3.4 Dual class firms in media industries vs. dual class firm in non-media industries Table 10 summarizes the results for the sub-sample of firms in media industries and the sub-sample of firms in non-media industries. The first few columns show that dual class firms in media industries do not have lower q values than their peers. All regressions report no statistically significant relationship between the DUAL dummy and Q, between insider ownership of voting rights and Q, or between voting rights-cashflow rights SEPERATION Index and Q. Hence, there is no convincible evidence that a dual class structure harms a media firm’s value. Next, the regressions of the sub-sample of dual class firms in the non-media industries show that the non-media dual class firms have lower Tobin’s Q values than their single class peers. All else equal, a dual class firm in a non-media industry has a Tobin’s Q which is 0.633 lower than that of a single class 42 firm. However, no statistically significant relationship between Tobin’s Q and insider ownership of voting rights is reported. The results are similar if I exclude financial firm with SIC code in the range of 6000-6999 and utility firms with SIC codes in the range of 4900. One potential benefit, initially identified by Demsetz and Lehn (1985), is that managers may experience a large utility payoff from being identified as the controlling party in certain high-profile firms, for example media firms and sports firms. This line of reasoning predicts that I should generally observe strong industry trends in the use of dual-class shares, and specifically I should observe many dual-class structures for firms in the media industry. My findings in the first essay are consistent with these predictions. The results in this section show that the dual class firms in the industries with the greatest control potential actually have the same value as single class firms in the same industries. One possibility is that there is not a traditional managerial entrenchment problem in media industries. However the results also show that there is a managerial entrenchment problem in non-media firms. Therefore, a more plausible explanation is that the control by insiders has certain benefits to the firm as a whole. In media industries, the product, business, and management are highly personalized. The business decisions frequently are determined by the personal tastes of management. For example, filmmaking, book and newspaper publishing and broadcast networks, depend more on personal style instead of mechanical operation. Personal creativity is key to success. Since it is hard to evaluate such stylized management, business and managerial decisions are challenged more frequently than in other industries. Without certain control, personalized or stylized business and management will not be able to be executed by insiders. The media firms 43 need to have constant stylized management and business strategy to survive. The dual class structure or high ownership of voting rights provides a relatively “stabilized” space for the managers to deliver and talented artists, filmmakers, and broadcasters to perform. This effect can be called managerial stabilization. The overall effect of management entrenchment and managerial stabilization on a media firm’s value resulting from dual class stock can be insignificant because of a counteracting effect. 2.4.4 Other Performance Measures Following similar reasoning, I also run regressions to determine if dual class firms underperform single class firms on other performance measures. The empirical specification is similar to equations (1) — (4). An alternative measure of performance is market-to-book equity ratio, market value of common stock divided by book value of common stock. The market-to book ratio is not as informative as Tobin’s Q. However, it still may be a useful measure of firm performance. Table 11 summarizes the regression results. There is no evidence in the regression of the full sample that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on market-to book equity ratio. The regression on the sub-sample of dual class firms that have two classes traded publicly and sub sample of firms in media industries yield same results. Overall, the results are inconsistent with the managerial entrenchment hypothesis. Table 12 summarizes the regression results of Price/Earning ratio. The regression results in all of the samples do not provide any evidence of underperforrnance of dual class firms. Note the R2 is very low for all of the regressions. Table 13 documents results of the regression of return on assets (ROA) in the full sample and sub-sample of dual class firms only. There is some evidence that dual class firms underperform the single class peers as measured by ROA. The coefficients of insider ownership of cash flow rights are positive and significant. ROA increases with insider ownership of cash flow rights. There is some evidence that ROA decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. In the regression with a piecewise specification for insider ownership of voting rights, ROA rises sharply as insider ownership increase from zero to 5%, RCA then decreases rapidly as insider ownership increases from 5% to 25%. There is some evidence that ROA decreases less rapidly as insider ownership of voting rights increases above 25%. This is consistent with some studies in that a low insider ownership of voting control of 0—5% is beneficial to firm performance. Table 14 demonstrates the results of the regression of EBIT/ Assets in the full sample and the sub-sample of dual class firms only. There is significant evidence that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on the aspect of EBIT/Assets. The coefficients of insider ownership of cash flow rights are positive and significant. EBIT/Assets increases with insider ownership of cash flow rights. There is also evidence that EBIT/Assets decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. In the piecewise regression for insider ownership of voting rights, EBIT/Assets rises rapidly as insider ownership increases from zero to 5%, EBIT/Assets then decreases less rapidly as insider 45 ownership increases from 5% to 25%. There is some evidence that EBIT/assets decreases less rapidly as insider ownership of voting rights increases above 25%. Table 15 demonstrates the results from the regression of Operating Cash Flow/ Assets in the full sample and the sub-sample of dual class firms only. There is significant evidence that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on the aspect of Cash Flow/Assets. The coefficient of insider ownership of cash flow rights is positive and significant. Cash Flow/Assets increases with insider ownership of cash flow rights. There is also evidence that Cash Flow/Assets decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. In the regression with a piece wise specification for insider ownership of voting rights, Cash Flow/Assets rises rapidly as insider ownership increases from zero to 5%, Cash flow/Assets then decreases less rapidly as insider ownership increases from 5% to 25%. There is some evidence that Cash Flow/assets decreases less rapidly as insider ownership of voting rights increases above 25%. In summary, there is no evidence that dual class firms underperform single class peers on certain performance measures, such as Market-to-book equity ratio and Price/Earnings ratio. There some evidence that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on some other performance measures, such as ROA, EBIT, and operating cash flow. Of these measures, firm performance rises with insider ownership of cash flow rights and decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. 2.4.5 Dividend policy in dual class firms 46 Table 7A shows that dual class firms in media industries pay less dividends than the matching single class firms while dual class firms in non-media industries do not pay less dividends. I use various regression models to study the factors that affect firm dividend payouts. I first estimate DIVIDEND/CAPITAL = a + b DUAL +c W + e (6) where DUAL is a dummy variable that equals 1 for dual class firms and 0 for single class firms. Wi is a vector of firm characteristics. As elements of W, I use the log of the book value of assets, the log of firm age, Operating Cashflow/Assets, Tobin’s Q and dummy variables for each of the two-digit SIC codes. EBIT/Assets, Net Income/Assets, Liquidity, Debt ratio, the book value of assets, and age are also used as a robustness check. More specifically, I can estimate the effect of the separation of voting rights and cash flow rights on dividend payout. I estimate DIVIDEND / CAPITAL = a + b DUAL + c CASH + d W + e (7) and DIVIDEND/CAPITAL=a+bVOTE+cCASH+dW+e (8) where CASH is the ownership of cash flow rights of insiders and VOTE is the ownership of voting rights of insiders. Table 17 reports the regression results. Concerning firms in the media industries, dual class firms pay significantly less dividends (Dividends/Capital ratio) than single class firm, as the coefficient for dummy Dual is -0.028 (t statistic = -3.846). In non-media industries, dual class firms do not have a lower dividend payout than single class firms. More interestingly, in a media firm, insider ownership of voting rights is positively related to Dividends/Capital ratio while insider ownership of cashflow rights is positively 47 related to Dividends/Capital ratio. For a media firm, a 10 percentage point increase in insider ownership of voting rights decreases the Dividend/Capital ratio by .0073, while a 10 percentage increase in insiders ownership of cashflow rights decreases the Dividend/Capital ratio by 0.0062. This also proves that control potential is high in media industries in that the insiders can manipulate the dividend payout without penalty on firm valuation — as shown earlier in media industries dual class firms do not have a different Tobin’s Q from single class firm. The managers will pay out more dividends if they have a larger stake in dividend cash flow rights. The insiders will pay out less dividends if they have more control in voting rights so they can have more cash flow to spend. From this angle, the dual class structure does provide the necessary condition for entrenchment. However, dual class firms in media industries do not have lower values. The results are similar if I exclude financial firms with SIC codes in the range of 6000-6999 and utility firms with SIC codes in the range of 4900. 2.5 Conclusion In this chapter I examined the relationship between firm value and dual class common stock. If the dual class structure protects inefficient incumbent managers from control contest as the managerial entrenchment hypothesis states, a prediction is a lower Tobin’s Q for a dual class firm compared with its industry peers. On the other hand, according to the shareholder interest hypothesis, a dual class structure creates a level of stability that can be beneficial by mitigates the under-investment problem or encouraging 48 human capital investment. If this were true, the prediction is that dual class firms will not have a lower Tobin’s Q. To investigate these issues I identify the dual-class status and insider ownership of voting rights and cashflow rights of all Compustat listed firms in 1995. Consistent with the shareholder interest hypothesis, I find that overall that dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms. However, dual class firms that have both classes traded publicly do have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms and Tobin’s Q increases as insider ownership of cash flow rights rises and declines as insider ownership of voting rights rises — only valid in this sub-sample. I also find that dual class firms that have one class of stock traded publicly do not have lower a Tobin’s Q than single class firms. Consistent with the shareholder interest hypothesis, I find within media industries, dual class firms do not have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firm. But within non- media industries, dual class firms have a lower Tobin’s Q than single class firms. Overall the findings suggest that dual class stock is beneficial if there is strong managerial comrrritment to the firm or there if there is a strong need for managerial stabilization. There is managerial entrenchment problem when the dual class firms have both classes traded publicly or when non-media firms issue dual class stock. Besides Tobin’s Q, there is no evidence that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on certain performance measures, such as Market-to-book equity ratio and Price/Earnings ratio. There is some evidence that dual class firms underperform their single class peers on some other performance measures, such as ROA, EBIT, and operating cash flow. Of these measures, firm performance rises with insider ownership of cash flow rights and decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. 49 In media industries, dual class firms pay less dividends than single class firms, the dividend payout increases as insider ownership of cash flow rights rises and declines as insider ownership of voting rights rises. The fact that managers can manipulate dividend payouts demonstrates the large control potential in media industries. 50 CHAPTER 3 Dual-class Stock, Investment and Cash Flow 3.1 Introduction Many studies show that internal capital is an important determinant of investments. Following Fazzari, Hubbard, and Peterson (1988), several studies demonstrate that cash flow is a more important determinant of investment for firms that are most likely to be constrained by internal capital when they invest.11 Lamont (1997) and Shin and Stulz (1998) provide evidence from another angle. Investments of segments of a diversified firm are dependent on cash flow from other segments. In general this literature provides evidence that when firms invest there is a significant difference between the cost of internal capital and external capital. However, the source of the difference in the cost of capital has not been fully explained. Myers and Majluf (1984) and Greenwald, Stiglitz, and Weiss (1984) show that there is a premium on external funds arising from contracting and information problems. According to this hypothesis, the relationship between liquidity and investment is typically a symptom of underinvestment. Firms pass up some positive NPV projects because of the cost of external capital. An alternative hypothesis is agency problem oriented. The free cash flow theory developed by Jensen (1986) and Stulz (1990) shows that managers overspend internal capital on unprofitable projects. The reality is not that ” For empirical evidence on the two explanations see Vogt (1994), Carpenter (1995), Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer (1994) and Jung. Kim. and Stulz (1996). 51 external capital is too expensive but is that internal capital is too inexpensive. The relationship between cashflow and investment is a symptom of overspending. It is an important issue to distinguish the two explanations for empirical relevance. Many previous empirical tests do not yield conclusive results.12 Hadlock (1998) examines how managerial ownership, or more generally the alignment of the interests between managers and shareholders, affects the sensitivity of investment to cash flow. Hadlock (1998) finds a nonlinear relationship between insider shareholdings and the sensitivity of a firm’s investment to its cash flow. As insider holdings increase from zero, investment-cash flow sensitivities rise sharply. This relationship weakens at high levels of insider ownership. Investment-cash flow sensitivities decrease slowly with insider holdings after a certain point. In my dual class firm sample insider ownership of voting rights and cash flow rights is separated. This separation provides an approach to study the entrenchment effect on investment-cash flow problem. 3.2 Hypothesis Development The free cash flow hypothesis advanced by Jensen argues that managers have a propensity to overinvest internal cash. Managers are not the owners of the firm and the interests of mangers and shareholders are not perfectly aligned. Managers may reap personal benefit from overinvesting without fully internalizing the costs of the investment decision borne by outsider shareholders. If a firm has free cash flow, managers will spend a large fraction of the firm’s internal funds. If a firm does not have free cash flow '2 See Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1991), Oliner and Rudebusch (1992), Whited (1992), Fazzari and Peterson (1993), Himmelberg and Peterson (1994) and Calomiris and Hubbard (1995). 52 managers will not invest as much since the external financing through capital markets disciplines managers and managers do not want be monitored. This investment behavior will generate a positive relationship between investment and cash flow. The free cashflow problem arises because insider ownership of cash flow rights is too low to align the interests of insiders and shareholders. Thus, managers overinvest. Therefore, firms with levels of low inside ownership of cash flow rights will exhibit a substantial sensitivity of investment to cash flow. For a firm with free cash flow but a high insider ownership of cash flow rights, managers' interests are well aligned with shareholders and thus we expect that they will make investment decisions that maximize the return to shareholders. The managers will invest at the efficient level and ignore the amount of free cash flow in making investments. The investment level of a firm does not depend substantially on the level of cash flow. So firms with higher insider ownership of cash flow rights will exhibit a relatively low sensitivity of investment to cash flow. On the other hand, when a firm has a high level of insider ownership of voting rights, managers will feel free to overspend without the presence of effective monitoring. If a firm has free cash flow then managers will spend the free cash flow without much discretion. Hence, firms with high insider ownership of voting rights will exhibit a substantial sensitivity of investment to cash flow. For a firm with free cash flow but a low level of insider ownership of voting rights, managers have to be cautious with investment decisions that do not maximize the return to shareholders. The managers will invest at a more efficient level and the amount of free cash flow is less in making investments. In this situation, the investment level of a firm depends substantially less on level of cash 53 flow. The reasoning implies that firms that have free cash flow with low ownership of voting rights will exhibit relatively low investment-cash flow sensitivities. Myers and Majluf (1984) demonstrate how a firm underinvests in the presence of asymmetric information problems in the capital markets. Myers and Majluf (1984) assume that mangers act in the interests of shareholders when making the investment and financing decisions, which needs a more essential assumption that firms typically have a high ownership of cash flow rights. Dybvig and Zender (1991) show that if managerial ownership is low, the underinvestment problem in alleviated. Hadlock (1998) uses a model of investment under asymmetric information where investment is a function of both cash flow and managerial ownership. Hadlock (1998) has shown that investment- cash flow sensitivity is increasing in managerial ownership. Based on these models, I infer that the underinvestment problem worsens as insider ownership of cash flow rights increases, which should imply that investment-cash flow sensitivity is increasing in insider ownership of cash flow rights. On the other hand based on empirical studies on entrenchment, I infer that the underinvestment problem is alliviated as insider ownership of voting rights increases, which should imply that the investment-cash flow sensitivity is increasing in insider ownership of cash flow rights. 3.3 Regression Specification Following the model in Hadlock (1998) and the regression specification in Shin and Stulz (1999), I use the following regression model: I/A = BOQ + BlF/A + Bz(F/A)*Voteright + B3(F/A)*Cashright +Y + s (6) 54 Where I is investment, F is cash flow, A is total assets, Q is a measure of Tobin’s q, Voteright is the insider ownership of voting rights, Cashright is insider ownership of cash flow rights and Y is controls. If firms face asymmetric information problems, I expect B3 to be positive and, if entrenchment effects are important, [32 to be negative. If firms face free cash flow problems, I expect (3;; to be negative and, if entrenchment effects are important, 32 to be positive. If asymmetric information problems and free cash flow problems do not affect firms investment decisions, I expect B3 and [32 to equal to zero. 3.4 Estimation Results The first a couple of columns in Table 16 are the regression results from the full sample of firms including single class firms and dual class firms. Column 1 reports estimates from a standard investment-cash flow regression fOr the entire sample of 1995. As in previous studies, the coefficient on Q is positive and significant. However, lagged sales is not significant. The estimated coefficient on cash flow of .015 is highly significant but smaller in magnitude to the cash-flow coefficient estimates reported by Fazzari, Hubbard and Peterson (1988) and Hadlock (1998). My full sample is much larger than that in previous studies and contains a large number of small companies. That may be part of the reason for the difference. Column 2 includes terms interacting cash flow with insider ownership of cash flow rights and voting rights. The regression on the full sample does not show that insider ownership affects investment-cash flow sensitivity. Again this may be due to the large number of small firms in the sample. 55 Column 3 reports estimates from a standard investment cash flow regression for the dual class firm sample in 1995. As in previous studies, the coefficient on Q is positive and significant. However, lagged sales is not significant. The estimated coefficient on cash flow is positive and not significant. At least part of the reason is that the dual class firm sample is very small. Column 4 includes terms interacting cash flow with insider ownership of cash flow rights and voting rights. The estimated coefficient on cash flow of -.O28 is small and insignificantly different form zero. This implies that for a firm with no insider ownership in either cash flow rights or voting rights, investment is not sensitive to cash flow. The estimated coefficient on cash flow interacted with insider ownership of cash flow rights is highly significant. The sensitivity of investment to cash flow increases rapidly with insider ownership of cash flow rights. The coefficients on cash flow interacted with insider ownership of voting rights is significant at the 1% level, implying that the sensitivity of investment to cash flow decreases rapidly with insider ownership of voting rights. Note that the R2 is as high as 0.9146. These estimates support the asymmetric information theories. The results are inconsistent with the free cash flow theories. The conclusion is similar to that of Hadlock (1998). As managers care more about shareholder value the asymmetric information problem becomes more severe. 3.5 Conclusion 56 An intriguing issue in the investment literature on financial constraints is the question of why firms behave as if there is a difference between internal and external capital. A large body of literature argues that capital market imperfections result in a premium on external capital. Hoshi, Kashyap, Sharfstein (1991) and Hubbard, Kashyap and Whited (1995) provide some evidence that free cash flow problems do not explain the observed relationship between cash flow and investment. However, their evidence is indirect and skeptics remain. Hadlock (1998) provides evidence that investment becomes more sensitive to cash flow as insider holdings increase from an initial point of zero. However, the entrenchment effect on investment is less conclusive as investment-cash flow sensitivity stops increasing in ownership after ownership reaches an unclear level. The separation of voting rights and cash flow rights in dual class firms provides a good ground to study the investment-cash flow sensitivity. In this chapter I have presented direct evidence that is inconsistent with the free cash flow problems driving the observed sensitivity of investment to cash flow. If the sensitivity of investment to cash flow was caused by free cash flow problems, the sensitivity of investment to cash flow should decrease as managers care more about shareholder value. However I find that there is evidence that investment-cash flow sensitivity increases with insider ownership of cash flow rights and investment-cash flow sensitivity decreases with insider ownership of voting rights. I am able to explicitly demonstrate the managerial entrenchment effect on investment-cash flow relation. The finding presented above is consistent with the asymmetric information theories on explanation of investment —cash flow sensitivity. The asymmetric information problems become more severe as managers care more about shareholder value. My 57 findings add to the literature suggesting that capital market imperfections result in a premium on external capital. 58 APPENDICES 59 APPENDIX A TABLES FOR CHAPTER 1: DUAL-CLASS STOCK AND THE BENEFITS OF CONTROL 60 Table A1. Number of US Firms With Dual Class Common Stock in 1990-1999 Year Number of firms Number of firms with dual in Total Class common stocks 1990 5320 379 1991 5392 396 1992 5633 417 1993 6579 455 1994 6921 494 1995 8286 391 1996 8138 563 1997 8902 573 1998 9310 566 1999 7198 544 Note - The full sample is composed of all firms listed on Compustat from 1990 to 1999. Foreign firms (ADR) and limited partnerships are excluded. The dual class firm sample includes firms with multiple classes of stocks. 61 Table A2. Description of the Variables Dual Inpct Inpct_1 Assets_l Assets-4 Lgasset Equity_1 Age Salegrow_l Salegrow-4 Liquid_l Liquid-4 DE_1 DE-4 MB_1 MB-4 PE_1 PE-4 Publish Broadcast Fin Insure Estate Utility mpicture STDf_l STDt_l dummy variable, equals one for dual class firms, zero otherwise. percent of common stock hold by insiders. precious year’s percentage of common stock hold by insiders. previous year’s total assets. average of previous four year’s total assets logarithm of previous year’s total assets pevious year’s market value of equity proxy for a firm’s actual age. Defined as current year — first year listed on CRSP sales growth in previous year average sales growth in previous four years liquidity in previous year average liquidity in previous four years debt to equity ration in previous year, Compustat (data5[t-1] +data9[t-1])/data216[t-1] average debt to equity ratio in previous four years market to book ratio in previous year, Compustat data25[t-l] *data199[t-1]/data60[t-1] average market to book ratio in previous four years P/E ratio in the previous year average P/E ratio in the previous four years dummy, equals one if SIC code is between 2700 and 2800, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC code is between 4800 and 4900, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC is between 6000 and 6300 or SIC is between 6700 and 6800, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC is between 6300 and 6500, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC is between 6500 and 6600, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC is between 4900 and 5000, zero otherwise dummy, equals one if SIC is between 7800 and 7900, zero otherwise standard error of estimate from the market model in which firm’s monthly return in previous four years is regressed on the average monthly return of the value-weighted market portfolio standard deviation of monthly stock market rates of return in the previous four year 62 80¢; 3.9.2 mwm. memo N.mm0~ Wan _ S moom o 33. 0.80— 0360 v-8mm< hmwmc 3mm: 3 o. Sema— n.wm§ w _ m.m0_ mgomm o M02. 5.00m _ :.wm .1336. 2.5 Saw; 0322 BO. 302 mdm: 9&3 0303 o chow 0.002 02.00 88.02.. .58. 0mg.“ 3 .wm mi m: mg... 2%. 5.2. 053m QUE..- 304. vam. @09. Yaocwufim mflm. fawn T 034. 0:3. awe. wvwwm m0m..- wmw0 3mm: memo. .IBEonm ***ow0m.m $5.0 _- 0mg. 29. 02.0. 00.9:V 00d- 36 03%. $00. 5380 8.5m 33.- afiwmm o minom oafim 20; 3.0? 0 mad. me.m vow; v-92 gem; QWNS o mms 29m 804 5.33 o 0.9» 0o:V mam; _Im2 40000.. 2.: o 2.0 aid 3 2 000 o mméa 2.3. EN; 2:: m2 2:: 356m 00mm. imam 09m- mvfi v.08 www.0v mmwmv :Vmwv- moi madam 30.2 03:5 xoom Dunn. Sham C03”.— 03. 3.000 3.02 5.8000 02 N. wbvm w.mm0 02.0 «Axiom 2.0—. oommm Pow. wénfl Néwm NS 320 o mm0m w.m©0 03.3. .rbicm EE 0 095cm ammo. E mom ammo. o0: $.me £30 50000 mummoo. Comm 8.03 03.3 2:? Exam—2 002. mm _ mm Nmmm- mg. 8.3m moose «mm? 0.02.? vME 0.8m 2.0.x— EEV .933 .28. $2 8 e- 2.2 $6 m 8 a- 3.2 3.2 A a? 9004. 39 23 fifl owe £2 32 mmo. v.2 $2 one mmmu :o :6» LEE .2. _ mmvN- 2o: Sm- 5:: 3&0 mtgm 0002 $00- @me E .0v mmoé EEC 6:96 waste? 90.. imma— o owns 0.009 $.02 0nmm§ omwé- N0? Némw 3.0 3:: 33m 58—2 £2 Om :32 52022 x32 :22 am :32 5:022 33:. Race . 202:3 .50 3.2;. 295% SE 3.20 .25 2&an =5 3.: 5 was... .s 23% as 8:535 555.5 .2 2.5 63 as. .03 as s 28:290.... .92 .03 as a 28:50.... .22 0.“ as a sscema... :26. 003 2: a E80E05... - 202 000 0000 3:0 0o 50:52 .1 _00._ N00. 0000. 0000. 000.. .3 00. 0000. _ 000. 0000. 00_ 0. 00000. 1.500 30000.0 0000. 00000. 000. 00_ _. N000. _ 000. 0000. 0000. 000_. 000_. 00.00 000 0. _ 0000. 00000. 0000. 000.. .00_. 0000. 0000. N. 00. 002. 00. _. 15-00 .0000.— 0000. 0 _ 000. 00000. 000 _. 0N_ _. 0000. 0000. 0000. 000.. 000_. 5.00 $0000. 000. 00000. 0000. 0000. 0000. 0000. 00-0000 000. 0000. 050. 169: ._. $00000- 0000. 00000. 0000. 00_ 0. 0000. 00000. 00-00. .0 0000. 000. 000_. 80:— 0000. _ - 00.000 0 .000 00.00 00.0_ 00.000 0 00.00 :40 _0.0_ 0-mm 00_ 0.- 000. 0 .000— 0000 00.: 0000 0 00. _ 0 00.00 000.0 7mm 2me 30000.0 0000— 0 00.00 00.0_ 000.0 0000 0 00.00 2.00 000.0 0:_:.am\8_.£ 0000.7 0000— 0 _0.0_ 000.0 00: 0.000 0 000.0 000.0 000.. 005 0_0N._- 00.000 0 00.00 0000.0 0000. 0.000. 0 00.00 0000.0 020. _Imn_ 0000.- 0.000 0 00.0_ 00_ .0 000. .00 0 00.0_ 00. .0 000. 260 30G 1.0000. _ - 00 .0. 000. _ - 000. 0000. 0000. 0000.0 000_ - 00.0. 0000.- 0000. 0-0505 $00000- 0000. 000.0- 0000. 0.00. 0_ 00. 000.00 0007 00.00 _000.- 0000. _IE:05 1000—0- 0000. 0.- 0000. 0000. 0000. _ 000 _- 0.0_ 0000.- 000_. 2:: 2:05 532 ES Gm 532 5622 x32 0:2 00 :82 .8602 $82: 3:00 035:3 50 3.2-.0 20:80 SE 3.03 :25 29:00 :2”— 33 5 2:3 E 29.50 as 800.50 0.25% €35.59 .3. ass-0 64 SS.- 888 80.. 80: 28 .08 888 88. 88. 88 ~32 0.3.... 8.0.- $28 8... 80: K: 02.8 2.88 o 8% Sn. .08 .43.... 88..- 888 8... 208 08% 0.8 080: o 8.8 0.3.8 9%. .._e:.aw_...so.- 0.8.- 8.02 .8...- ms... 80... 9.... 8.8“ 2%..- 08... 88. 82. 0-32028 omn- 808 83.- 2.2 $8. 8... 8.0% 8.....- 83 :8. .8... .13o.w....m 8:.- 38m 8....- QN. 28.0 82. 380 88..- 2.9. $0.. 38.. 53203.8 $.85... 8m: 8 :2. 82 08.. o8. 0 9.0.0 9.0.. 2.0 0-..: 8%.. .08 o .80. 200 80. 88 o 8...... :3 8.0. .02 1.8.0 2.: o ....m 9.3 w... 88 o 8.8 2.3. 20. 82...... 2.5 0.5.0. 1.08.0- 08.: 38¢ 3.8.. 38 0...“. 28.: 8.2...- 028 3% 0.8....“ 22> .00.. 88.- 2.2... 88. 05 NS. N8 .820 88. 8.: an. 8.2. 1.3.8 8.0.- 88m. 0%... .88 08. .8 Q82 0 38. a: 0.8 1.5.5 260.95%. 88m..- 85$ 8:. 58. 3.08 8.8.. 88% 288. to... 2: 8.0.. U.....>§.._.§. .55 :23- 89: 0.58- 29. 2.8 8.0... Re: 058- $8 0.5 00% 053.28 .80 E o :0. am... 0 i o 000. 8... 0 cm... ammo 08:.- 8 8 2.: 3... 8 8 8 .02 .5 8 8.8.2.... .55 ~82- 8% 89... m.... 8.8. at... 080. 8.”...- 03 9.2: 3.3. 2.0.5808... 28..- 0.2: o 3.8. 22 0.80 23. 8.0.- 8% 0...... 0.3.. 95:28 mcmvEEzcu 08.). ES. Om :32 5:00.). .83. ES. Om 0.3.). 5:002 5:02-... 0.0800 6.... 80.0 .25 0.0600 :2". 0.0.00.0} 0000 :. 95.0 00 20:80 .3 8.6.3.0 0.85:50 .04. 0.00..- 65 .26. .0.... 6... a 280.85....- .6.6. .00... 65 .6 58.0.8.0 .3...- ..66. .00 2.. .0 28020.0 .3. .26. .00. 2.. a 2.30.8.0 .- 66 000 00.0 06.... 0o ..00::.Z 1......0. 00.0 00.0. .000. . 000. .0... 0000. 0000.. .0000. 00000. 000.. 000.. .0000 1.2000 0 .0 0000. 00000. 00000. .00.. 000. . .000 . . 00000. 00000. 000. . . 0. .. 1.0.00 0.00.- 0. 00. 00000.0 00. 0. 0. 00. 000. . 0000. 00-0000 0000. 0000. 000. . .1800. .0000..- 000. 0 00.00 ...00 00.0. 000. 0 00.00 00.00 00.0. 0-0.0 .0000..- 0000 0 0.00. 00.00 00.0. 0000 0 00.. 0 00.00 000.0 .19. 005. 0000. 0.00. 0 00. .0 000.0. 000.0 00.0000 0 0.00. 00.00 000.0 00.0-50.0005 00...- 00.00 0 000.0 000.0 000.. 0.000 0 00.0. 000.0 0000. 0-0.0. 000. . 0.000 0 0. .0. 000.0 00 . 0. 0000 0 00.00 .000 0000. .Imn. 000 .. 00.00 0 000 .0 000.0 0000. 00.000. 0 00.00 000.0 0000. 2.3. .000. 000..- 0000. 0000.0- 00. 0. 0.0.. 0000. . 00.00- .00.. 0. 0.. 0000. 0.0505 0000..- 0000. 00.0- 00.0. ..0.. 0.0.. . 000- 0.0.0 00.000. 00 . 0. .0505 $0. ..0- 0000. 000.0- 0000. 000.. 000.. . 000.- 00.0. 0000.- 00. 0. 0...: 08.05 0.80:. .0300 .83. 52 Q0 5.0.). 00.00.). .83. ES. Q0 5.0.). 00.00.). .00 .00..-.- 0.0.00.5 0.0..-.00 EE 8.0.0 .020. 20:80 :3". 000— :. 0:5,.— ..0 0.0500 .80 8.00.050 0.85.5.0 2.0.5.3000 .0< 0.00.0 Table A5. Distribution of Dual Class Firms in Certain Industries in 1990 and 1999 1990 1999 Industry Dummy Full Sample Dual class Full sample Dual class firm sample firm sample Publish 83 24 84 24 Broadcast 122 26 204 53 Finance 5 89 27 1 l 13 55 Insurance 157 19 209 19 Real Estate 62 3 69 5 Utility 260 8 194 5 Motion picture 62 ll 51 7 Number of firms 5320 379 7198 544 in total Note- Publishing industry includes firms with SIC codes between 2700 and 2800. Broadcasting industry includes firms with SIC codes between 4800 and 4900. Financial industry includes firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6300 or SIC between 6700 and 6800. Insurance industry includes firms with SIC code between 6300 and 6500. Real estate industry includes firms with SIC between 6500 and 6600. Utility industry includes firms with SIC between 4900 and 5000. Motion picture industry includes firms with SIC between 7800 and 7900. 67 Table A6. Logit Regressions of Sample of Firms in 1990 Independent variables and 1 2 3 summary statistics Assets 4.8e-06 6.7e-06 -.000204** (.791) (1.112) (-2.297) Age -.00844 -.001570 (-1.344) (-.207) Salegrow -.004821 (~. 144) Liquid -. 1520 (-.420) Debt/Equity .008968 (1.558) Market lbook -.0071 19 (-0.790) price/eaming -.004175 (-l.334) Publisher(dummy) l.687***** 1.653***** 1.668***** (5.417) (5.292) (5.108) Broadcast(dummy) .7181* .677* .6669 (1.813) (1.711) (1.306) Utility (dummy) -2.845**** -2.802*** -2.738*** (-2.8 19) (-2.775) (-2.692) Finance (dummy) -.676l** -.7615*** -.2290 (-2.316) (-2.590) (-.312) Insurance (dummy) .4894 .4385 .5751 (1.416) (1.295) (.757) Estate (dummy) -l.008 -1.005 dropped in (-.0991) (-.989) reg Mpicture (dummy) 1.408** 1.385M l.723**** (2.462) (2.420) (2.873) STDf -3.530*** -4.250**** -6.32***** (-2.621) (-2.889) (3.572) Intercept —2.256 ~2.019 -1.663 (-12.62) (8.09) (-5.209) Log-likelihood -722.83 -721.88 -583.30 Number of 3 164 3 164 2522 Observations Note - Logit regression of the probability of issuing dual class common stock on accounting and stock return data. The dependent variable is a dummy that equals one if a firm has a dual common stock and 0 otherwise. Publish, broadcast, utility, finance. insurance, estate and mpicture industry dummies. t-statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 68 Table A6. (Continued) Logit Regressions of Sample of Firms in 1990 Independent variables and 4 5 6 summary statistics Insider ownership 1.343***** (3.352) Assets 0000152“ (2.422) assets-4 -.00027** (-2.418) Equity -.64e-05* (- l .730) Age -.006281 -.000824 -.818 (-. 106) Salegrow-4 .001132 (.054) Liquid-4 -.08372 (-. 197) debt/equity-4 .009198 (.542) Market/book-4 .009642 (1.328) price/earning -4 -.002947 (-.735) Publisher (dummy) 1.662***** 2.062***** 1.53***** (5.335) (6.330) (4.596) Broadcast(dummy) .9760** .9422** .6414 (2.407) (2.047) (1.266) Utility (dummy) -2.83**** dropped -2.690*** (~2.803) in reg (-2.636) Finance(dummy) -.6770** -.4890 -. 1894 (-2.397) (-1.214) (-.257) Insurance (dummy) .5268 .8530** .6212 (1.572) (2.334) (.800) Estate (dummy) -1.053 -.5462 dropped (- 1.036) (-.532) in reg Mpicture (dummy) 1.439** l.552** 1.776**** (2.513) (2.345) (2.910) STDf 4.54“” -3.990** -6.13***** (-3. 155) (~2.065) (-3.349) Intercept -2.083 -2.719 -1.736 (-10.86) (-8.410) (5.046) Log-likelihood -719.70 -524.45 -574.62 Number of 3141 2309 2408 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 69 Table A7. Logit Regression of Sample of Firms in 1990-1994 Logit estimate of the dependence of dual/multiple class common stock structure probability on accounting and stock return data. The dependent variable is a dummy that equals one if a firm has a dual/multiple common stcok structure. Independent variables . and summary statistics 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 total assets-4 3.76e-06 4.00e-06 4.04e-06 2.90e-06 1.80e-06 (.450) (.547) (.595) (.416) (.273) Age -.0116** -.0109* -.01334** -.0164*** -.0145** (-1.796) (- l .789) (-2.290) (-2.772) (~2.526) Publisher (dummy) 1.582***** 1.529***** 1.517***** l.71***** l.72***** (5.03) (5.035) (4.998) (5.78) (5.945) Broadcast .5879 1.018**** .9966***** l.20***** 1.09***** (dummy) (1.47) (2.996) (3.179) (4.12) (3.581) Utility -2.947**** -2.32***** -1.94***** -1.123*** -1.166 (dummy) (-2.917) (-3.218) (-3.282) (-2.623) ( 1.3975) Finance -.8419*** -.8297*** -.930***** -.843**** -.8067**** (dummy) (~2.671) (~2.762) (~3.346) (—3. 124) (2979) Insurance .4220 .5999** .24009 .04772 .006675 (dummy) (1.181) (2.015) (.801) (.144) (.984) Estate -1.021 -.9819 -1.024 -.7331 -.6914 (dummy) -l.003 (—.965) (-1.006) (-.718) (-.676) Mpicture (dummy) 1.431** 1.262** 1.1836** 1.131** l.398**** (2.491) (2.488) (2.546) (2.233) (2.935) STDf _10.4***** -l0.0***** _6.82***** 4.3***** .4'56***** (-4.431) (-4.710) (-4.287) (-3.66) (-3.831) S'I'Df2 13.44***** 12.95***** 6.411***** 1.212** 1.1959“ (3.956) (4.311) (3.756) (2.684) (1.984) Intercept -l .472 -1.494 -1.593 -l.720 -1.683 (-5.013) (-5.393) (-6.740) (7.972) (—7.622) Log-likelihood -703.50 -78l.96 -884.73 -896.60 -896.61 number of 3081 3345 3596 3579 3547 observations Note - Logit regression of the probability of issuing dual class common stock on accounting and stock return data. The dependent variable is a dummy that equals one if a firm has a dual common stock and 0 otherwise. Publish, broadcast, utility, finance, insurance, estate and mpicture are indusU'y dummies. t- statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 70 Table A8. Logit Regression of Sample of Firms in 1995-1999: Logit estimate of the dependence of dual/multiple class common stock structure probability on accounting and stock return data. Independent variables , and summary statistics 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 total assets-4 1.54e-06 3.62e-07 3.42e-07 l .32e-06 8.62e-06 (.251) (-062) (.946) (.320) (.228) Age -.0144** -.0211***** -.01395*** -.008225* -.00903* (-2.554) (-3.652) (-2.672) (-1.706) (-1.906) Publisher (dummy) 1.73***** 1.737***** l.693***** l.75***** l.7l6***** (5.969) (6.207) (6.080) (6.157) (5.842) Broadcast 1.25***** 1.025***** 1.356***** 1.435***** 1.432***** (dummy) (4.008) (3.225) (4.700) (5.219) (5.039) Utility -1.173*** -1.245 -l.469**** -l.339**** -1.548**** (dummy) (~2.742) (-2.877) (-3. 138) (-2.866) (-2.981) Finance -.847***** -.6485*** -l.01***** -.925***** -1.09***** (dummy) (-3.043) (-2.653) (-4.298) (-4. 125) (.4830) Insurance .1326 -.3088 -.06688 -.0212 -. 1578 (dummy) (.414) (-.896) (-.231) (-.076) (-.531) Estate -.6719 .1372 -.1174 -.07635 -.0299 (dummy) (—.657) (.184) (-. 159) (-. 103) (-.040) Mpicture (dummy) 1.508***** 1.192** 1.118** l.062** -1.142** (3.353) (2.525) (2.202) (2.111) (2.226) STDf ~4.620***** -6.480* -8. 194** -7.10***** -7.78***** (-3.820) (-1.633) (-2.551) (-3.517) (-4.602) STD;2 l. 196* -2.189 3.382 4.7000 5.298“ (1.832) (-.182) (.369) (1.150) (2.310) Intercept -l.675 -1.245 -1.306 -1.556 -1.358 (-7.631) (-3.632) (-4.363) (-6.333) (-5.722) Log-likelihood -898.55 -945.81 998.28 -1055.85 - 1021.71 number of observations 3518 3593 3931 4104 3866 Note - The dependent variable is a dummy that equals one if a firm has a dual common stock and 0 otherwise. Publish, broadcast, utility, finance, insurance. estate and mpicture are industry dummies. t- statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 71 Table A9. Logit Regression of Sample of Firms in 1999 Independent variables and summary statistics 1 2 3 4 5 Insider ownership 1.034**** (3.046) Total Assets -1.03e-06 4.25e-07 -.0000231 (-.310) (.089) (-1.415) total assets-4 -.0000244 (-1.287) Equity -.0000132* (-l.910) Age -.005599 -.00909* -.00943* (-1.029) (-1.666) (-1.723) Salegrow -.42455* (-1.908) Salegrow-4 -.4079* (-1.941) Liquid .1401 (.451) Liquid-4 .09635 (.288) Debt/Equity .02132 (2.168) debt/equity-4 .01464* (1.833) market lbook -.04414** (-2.248) Market/book-4 -.02902 (-1.558) price/earning .0002664 (.677) price/earning -4 .001336* (1.749) Publisher (dummy) 1.747***** 1,7209***** 1.886***** 1.762***** l.76***** (5.963) (5.833) (5.797) (5.747) (5.701) Broadcast 1.482***** 1.6086***** 1.561 ***** 1.672***** 1.48***** (dummy) (5.234) (5.552) (4.665) (5.021) (4.406) Utility -1.591**** -1.6237**** -l.289* -1.439*** -l.454*** (dummy) (-3.085) (-3. 139) (-2.155) (-2.738) (~2.760) Finance -.9358***** -l.014***** -1.063 -.9909 -l.0205 (dummy) (-4.356) (-4.684) (-3.660) (-.971) (-1.000) Insurance -.05683 -. 1046 .0635***** .8691 * .8298 (dummy) (-.l98) (-.355) (.201) (1.709) (1.642) Estate -.0633 -. 1051 -.5128 dropped in dropped in (dummy) (-.085) (-.141) (-.498) reg reg Mpicture (dummy) 1.167*** 1.205** 1.193** 1.235* 1.3906“ (2.279) (2.348) (2.012) (1.847) (2.340) STDf _4.860***** _7.252***** _6.07***** _6.67***** _7.8***** (-4.506) (-4.534) (—3. 188) (-4.702) (-4.283) STD.2 4.920** 3951* 5.688** (2.139) (1.601) (2.662) Log-likelihood - 1024.98 -1020.32 -808.10 -795.01 -803.53 number of observations 3877 3860 2967 2907 2882 72 Note - The dependent variable is a dummy that equals one if a firm has a dual common stock and 0 otherwise. Publish, broadcast, utility, finance, insurance, estate and mpicture are industry dummies. t- statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 73 APPENDIX B TABLES FOR CHAPTER 2: DUAL-CLASS STOCK, FIRM VALUE, AND PERFORMANCE 74 Table Bl. Description of the Variables DUAL Ownsuper Owninfer Sharesuper Shareinfer Votesuper Voteinfer Separation Vote rights Cash rights Size Size_l Lgsize Age Lgage Salegrow_l Liquid DE M/B equity PE Stdf Stdt R&D Advertising Investment Cashflow EBIT ROA Dividend dummy variable, equals one for dual class firms, zero otherwise. the insider ownership in the superior voting class the insider ownership in the inferior voting shares the number of shares outstanding in superior voting class the number of shares outstanding in inferior voting class the votes per share for the superior voting class the votes per share for the inferior voting class Insider ownership of voting rights/ Insiders ownership of cashflow rights Insider ownership of voting rights Insider ownership of cashflow rights total firm assets previous year’s total assets. logarithm of total assets proxy for a firrn’s actual age. Defined as current year - first year listed on CRSP logarithm of age sales growth in previous year Assets liquidity debt to equity ratio, Compustat (data + data9)/data216 market-to-book equity ratio, Compustat data25*data199/data60 Price/Earnings ratio standard error of monthly stock market rates of return in previous four years estimated from a market model in which firm’s monthly return in previous four years is regressed on the average monthly return on value-weighted market portfolio standard deviation of monthly stock market rates of return in previous four years Research and development expense/total assets Advertising expense/ total assets Capital expenditure/ total assets operating cashflow/ total asstes Earnings before interest and taxes/ total assets Net Income/ total assets Cash dividend! total capital 75 23m 8m. 0 - Q _ N..- 000: o 52: 0N0~ 3.9 N. g m0m o 0m.0o w0.- m.~_ wEEmmBotm iiimd- 85.. dem 0 Sim ooo.~ flaw. No: 0 Omgm $0; :00. 2:: Boa ammo. ***wwhd- «NE .- 9.5. 54.0. CM memo. $3.. 0 $9- 000 - Rom. 0:5 2:34 0 ***ixwd- 300.. $83 $0. 00m: 0.5m”: QwE memmnm o ammo ._ :1 0.5.. 7083‘ 0 2:: 33.5.2- 800.. mwmmvm 3.0. bvmmm 002 imam 030: o @002 .502 wN.:. mgomm< :23. 0:. wdwh. wm.m_ T 3 : :3. m: _. mm». 8.7 00.0 3.00. 23. 530.5 83m ommg- wa0. mdm 0 Sam wand 0w0._ 3.3. o v.00 __w.v «(00.— oE: 5:50 92 met was? .8 958,56 *****m.0_- iiium- _ o :5. 00mm. 3.00. mac. 0 w0om. mmmm. 3.3. 8055 30w: 25: 5.8 0c 9:20:30 ****i.md- $33.0- 030. o aim. 5.9%. mowm. whoa. o w0om. mmmm. 3.3. 505:— EEV bS—om ***iwwd- 000w: :mvm Emmw- «of mem vWNw 099. 042 _- «02 04mm 8.5 32> xcom *****m.w- omofi .- 0_ mwm ommg .2m :00 wdE 30$ 0 2.— m v0.0 0m.mm 1.3.23.0 BE 0.92.5 1.3.1.80- Rum: monm 58. mmmm ©wa Wm: owoo. _ 3:00. 009» 00: 91.0 62.3 8x82 09... 0vmm. o\. v- w. 2 0.2 w E. v- NE M2: N. ow< oov. 03m; age 32 w.: $9 $9 08— mme N.m_ Swo— wwo— ammo :c EPA 5.5 $33.36 50m. vwwm 35. mm.m v00; mmm._ Sow mmvm. 5m: Sand 30.. 0o 0 $508. $3.336 3%. 0.3: oo0m. Q06 mmm.m 05w— 0§w 0?. 000— omvé 3.0.. 0 £505. .502: :53 SSE 08—2 52 Om :32 22022 582 ES Om can—2 5:022 .50 an. 6.5: :33 6.03:3 -cwfi 080:3 5.. 52.. 29:3 EE mam—o :25 29:3 :2: $20 o_w:_m ma: 5 2:3 a. 295% .8 82.5w 3555 .2 2...; 76 ES. :0: .0 on: :0 anEcwfi 40:00:: E5025 5823:... .05. 000.0 20 S Ewe-2:06 0300:: 20:00:: 582:: $3. :0: of 3 2:89:06. 0300:: 33025 532...: _o>o_ :00 on: E Enucfiwi 40:00:: 23025 502...... 65. 000— 0:: E Ewe-:06 00:00:: A5025 :32... - 202 2:5 :00 0005 .6 508:2 3890 .310: .N- 00N0.- 00: ._ 0 000 _. .000. >000. 000.N 0 00: N. E 00. 0N00. \0:_m::o>0< *****N_0.0 v00N. 00.N 0 movN. 0000. 00.0. 000 0 N50: 00mm. 0500. 23.35000 $30000 3:000...“ 0000. NN00. 000. 000:. 0000. 000.0 0 : N0. 0000. :0N:. 000.. 000.0 130030 0.31000 300. NN00. 0000. 30:. 000:. N30 0: N0. 0000. 0N0 _. :N: _. no.“ 00 :3 o *****000.v- NO0N. 03 ._ 00N: .- N08. 0: N0. 0 0N.0m 0N0.N- N000. 0NNO. 0 \m0:M0_>__:Q :3 m it... : N06- 0NNm. N3.— 000N.- N000. 0 _ N0. 0 N: .0 N000- 000:. 00N0. 0 \m0co0_>5 00 £o$< 0:0. N0:0.- 0N: 000.0- 050. NON0. 0050. 00.0 00:- 000.N N90.- Kno. 350030 83?. 000.. N0 0 0 .- 5.0— 00.5 - 000.: >000. 00:0. 0000. 00_ 7 N00: 0NON.- _ 0 :0. 300080 00:. 0NNN; 0:0.0 00.N_- 030. 0000.- 0000. NNNN :0: - 00.m_ NO0N. 0N8. <00 03 . _ - 0:00.- 0N.0N 00.N_- 000.: 030. 0000. 000.0 0800- 00.0 000.- 2 >0. 332 2.5m 00 aomm< :0. 0000. 000.: 0 002. 0: 00. 02:0. 0N0 0 0NNN. :000. 0000. 22:39:: 23.3: N05- 000. _ - 00.3 0 0000. 003. 0000. 0.00 0 NON0. 30:. 0000. 05:58.»:— 00 00:: mi **00_.N- 11000.0- 0N; 0 0.0:.N 00: 00.0: 0.N:0N 0 00.00 0N.0N 0N: x32 52 D0 :32 5022 :82 52 D0 :32 50022 5200:: 0300 33:: 3:06 :8 :8: 0:0: :8 :8:- o_0:::0 E5 320 0:5 20an :5 o_02._:> :05 50:3 m9: 5 22:: .5 «Beam 8: 8:235 racism €35.50: .8 2.5 77 Table B3. Distribution of Dual Class Firms in Certain Industries in 1995 Industry Dummy Full Sample Dual class firms Publishing 96 22 Broadcasting 191 39 Finance 1269 19 Insurance 275 23 Real Estate 68 2 Utility 264 5 Motion picture 61 8 A gric ulture-Crops 15 2 Oil and gas extraction 216 4 Number of firms in total 8286 391 Note- publishing industry includes firms with SIC codes between 2700 and 2800. Broadcasting industry includes firms with SIC codes between 4800 and 4900. Financial industry includes firms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6300 or SIC between 6700 and 6800. Insurance industry includes firms with SIC code between 6300 and 6500. Real estate industry includes firms with SIC between 6500 and 6600. Utility industry includes firms with SIC between 4900 and 5000. Motion picture industry includes firms with SIC between 7800 and 7900. Agriculture-Creps industry includes firms with SIC between 0100 and 70200. Oil and extraction industry includes firms with SIC between 1300 and 1400. 78 Table B4.A. Insider Ownership in The Dual Classes Insiders are defined as executive officers and board directors. The insider ownership includes shares owned by officers and directors, trusts for their benefits and foundations or corporations they control. Super-voting Inferior-voting class class Mean insider ownership 6373* 2165* Medium insider ownership .7123** .1460** Total number of firms 289 * t=20.81 for hypothesis that mean insider ownership in super class is large than mean insider ownership in inferior class ** 2:13.51 for the Wilcox sign-rank test of the equal median insider ownership. Table B4.B. Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms Cash flow rights and voting rights are based on common stock ownership. SEPARATION Index is defined as insider ownership of voting rights divided by ownership of cash flow rights. Cash flow rights Voting rights Mean Insider rights 3465* 5480* Medium Insider rights .3225** .6058** Mean SEPARATION 1.87 Medium SEPARATION 1.50 Total number of firms 242 * t: 17.92 for hypothesis that mean insider voting rights in dual class firms is large than mean insider cashflow tights ** 2: 12.59 for the Wilcox sign—rank test for equal median. 79 Table B4.C. CEO Ownership in The Dual Classes Super-voting Inferior-voting class class Mean CEO ownership 3475* 0994* Medium CEO ownership .2505** .022** Total number of firms 290 * t=l3.53 for hypothesis that mean CEO ownership is larger in Super-voting class than mean CEO ownership in inferior-voting class. ** z =11.28 for Wilcox sign-rank test of the hypothesis that the median CEO ownership is larger in Super-voting class than median CEO ownership in inferior-voting class. Table B4.D. Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms in Media Industries and Non-media Industries Cash flow rights and voting rights are based on common stock ownership. Firms in media industries Firms in non-media industries Cash flow Voting Cash flow Voting Mean Insider rights .3318 .5340 .3413 .5508 Medium Insider rights .2612 .6249 .3202 .6021 Mean SEPARATION 1.793 1.891 Median SEPARATION 1.460 1.523 Total number of firms 44 202 80 Table B4.E. Insider Cash Flow Rights and Voting Rights in Dual Class Firms Cash flow rights and voting rights are based on common stock ownership. Both classes traded Only one class traded Jublicly publicly Cash flow Voting Cash flow Voting Mean Insider rights .3302 .4916* .3425 .5702* Medium Insider rights .3258 .522** .3141 .6378** Mean SEPARATION l.65*** l.96*** Median 1.41 1.52 SEPARATION Total number of firms 69 201 Table B4.F. The Largest Block Shareholder Ownership in The Dual Classes The block shareholder is defined as any person, corporation or institution that owns more than 5% of the class. Note there are no block shareholders in the inferior voting class in some firms. Super-voting Inferior-voting class class Mean largest block ownership .6013 .2725 Medium 1argest block .5667 .1929 ownership Total number of firms 292 255 81 Table B5. Summary Statistics for the Sample of Dual Class Firms and the Matching Firms Dual class firms are matched with peer single firms with the closest book assets in the same industry (same 2-di git SIC code). Dual class firms Matching single class firms Number Variable of Median Mean SD Median Mean SD observations Tobin’s Q 1.318 1.844 1.646 1.445 1.933 1.834 288 Q 96 1.388** 2.100 3.617 l.479** 2.083 2.645 315 PB 12.62 25.48 106.0 13.49 21.88 51.50 320 PE 96 14.01 36.34 177.1 13.07 33.58 180.7 350 Market/Book 1.651** 2.645** 3.260 2.094** 3.395** 4.803 326 equity Age 5** 9.148 11.77 7** 10.42 12.76 406 Debt ratio .889 2.223 5.449 .942 4.314 28.18 375 Investment .0556 .1539 .8429 .0652 .0957 .1076 336 Investment96 .0497 .1052 .2452 .0610 .1021 .2034 363 Cash flow .0845 .0881 1.251 .0876 .0224 .8009 363 Cash flow 96 .07884 -.00577 .5397 .0905 .00793 .4318 402 EBIT .0883 .1134 1.447 .0796 .0409 .6328 372 ROA .0373 -.0281 .6708 .0306 -.0377 .7912 372 Dividend 0 .0153 .1362 0 -.0039 .8055 429 Note - * different mean or median significant at the 10% level ** different mean or median significant at the 5% level *** different mean or median significant at the 1% level **** different mean or median significant at the 0.5% level ***** different mean or median significant at the 0.1% level Table B6.A. Summary Statistics for the Subsample of Dual Class Firms with Both Classes Traded Publicly and the Matching Firms Dual class firms are matched with peer single firms with the closest book assets in the same industry (same 2-digit SIC code). Dual class firms with both Matching single class firms Number of Variable classes traded observations Median Mean SD Median ' Mean SD Tobin’s Q 1.146*** 1454* 1.009 1.396*** 1.813* 1.567 68 Q 96 1.178** 1.458 .898 1.340** 1.809 1.785 64 PE 12.50 20.13 4.335 13.37 26.02 5.686 72 PE 96 12.62 23.61 48.44 14.81 41.18 140.2 71 Market/Book 1.613 2.494 3.086 2.187 3.165 3.642 74 equity Age 11 13.09 10.45 9 12.69 13.31 75 Debt ratio 1.110 1.776 2.566 1.018 1.771 1.929 70 Investment .0509 .0874 .1317 .0668 .091 1 .0849 74 Investment96 .0428 * * .0764 .1254 0648* * .0923 .1300 72 Cash flow .1007 .0623 .3480 .0948 .0927 .1 114 77 Cash flow 96 0935* .0684 .2686 .1165* .1012 .1363 76 EBIT .0904 .0641 .314 .0893 .101 .123 79 ROA .0439 .00903 .336 .0402 .0351 .102 79 Dividend .00549 .0240 .0448 .0124 .0508 .144 83 Note - * different mean or median significant at the 10% level ** different mean or median significant at the 5% level *** different mean or median significant at the 1% level **** different mean or median significant at the 0.5% level ***** different mean or median significant at the 0.1% level 83 Table B6.B. Summary Statistics for the Subsample of Dual Class Firms with Only One Class Traded Publicly and the Matching Firms Dual class firms are matched with peer single firms with the closest book assts in the same industry (same 2-di git SIC code). Dual class firms with only Matching single class firms Variable one class traded Number of observations Median Mean SD Median Mean SD Tobin’s Q 1.357 1.892 1.579 1.443 1.941 1.821 197 Q 96 ~ 1.414 2.262 4.194 1.476 2.072 2.583 226 PB 12.95 28.926 125.4 13.99 21.81 55.16 222 PB 96 14.73 30.85 118.6 12.64 33.73 200.8 249 Market/Book 1667* 2.637** 3.173 2.059* 3.395** 4.962 224 equity Age 4** 8.857 12.30 6** 10.15 12.79 286 Debt ratio .8274 2.392 6.267 .8759 3.920 24.94 264 Investment .0561 .1740 .9991 .0645 .0972 .1 156 231 Investment96 .0547 .1167 .2801 .0595 .1062 .2302 263 Cash flow .0841 .1483 1.240 .0854 .0031 .9534 251 Cash flow 96 .0801 -0.0058 .5454 .0841 -.00830 .4820 282 EBIT .0891 .1743 1.647 .0769 .02455 .7498 257 ROA .0365 .03812 .417 .0294 -0.0590 .9425 257 Dividend 0 .0123 .160 0 -0.229 .960 300 Note - * different mean or median significant at the 10% level ** different mean or median significant at the 5% level *** different mean or median significant at the 1% level **** different mean or median significant at the 0.5% level ***** different mean or median significant at the 0.1% level 84 Table B7.A. Summary Statistics for the Subsample of Dual Class Firms in Media Industries and the Matching Firms Media Industries includes SIC code from 2700 to 2799 (publishing), from 4800 to 4900 (broadcasting) and 7800 to 7900 (motion pictures). Dual class firms are matched with peer single firms with the closest book assets in the same industry (same 2-digit SIC code) Dual class firms in media Matching single class firms Variable industries Number of observations Median Mean SD Median Mean SD Tobin’s Q 1.616 1.761 .7262 1.762 1.789 .5736 46 Q 96 1.461 1.998 2.07 1.523 1.667 .776 50 PE 17.75** 3806* 86.88 0** 13.83* 25.13 49 PE 96 15.73** 107.5* 425.8 0** 13.97* 25.99 55 Market/Book 2.26** 3.2**** 4.33 3.74** 5.7**** 6.66 49 equity Age 3 7.09* 10.38 5 1044* 13.43 66 Debt ratio 124* 2.66 4.83 1.70* 9.14 46.98 61 Investment .0620 .170 .438 .1085 .136 .122 52 Investment 96 .0776* .197 .487 .0914* .207 .444 59 Cash flow .0925 .140 .396 .112 .0856 .151 59 Cash flow 96 .0807 .0430* .459 .1056 -.0162* .662 71 EBIT .0921 .1305* .4229 .0622 .0507* .1455 66 ROA .0348 -.0726 .7033 .0293 -.0108 .1558 66 Dividend 0* .0199** .0483 0* .0429** .0751 74 Note - * different mean or median significant at the 10% level ** different mean or median significant at the 5% level *** different mean or median significant at the 1% level **** different mean or median significant at the 0.5% level ***** different mean or median significant at the 0.1% level 85 Table B7.B. Summary Statistics for the Subsample of Dual Class Firms in Non- media Industries and the Matching Firms Media Industries includes SIC code from 2700 to 2799 (publishing), from 4800 to 4900 (broadcasting) and 7800 to 7900 (motion pictures). All other industries (SIC code from 0100 to 9999) are defined as non-media industries. Dual class firms are matched with peer single firms with the closest book assets in the same industry (same 2-digit SIC code) Dual class firms in non- Matching single class firms Variable media industries Number of observations Median Mean SD Median Mean SD Tobin’s Q 1.222 1.859 1.768 1.372 1.960 1.985 242 Q 96 .136** 2.119 3.84 l.447** 2.162 2.86 265 PB 12.15 23.21 109.1 13.80 23.15 54.87 271 PE 96 13.95 23.08 53.04 13.63 37.26 196.3 295 Market/Book 1.520 2.54* 3.03 1.87 2.99* 4.29 equity Age 5 9.55 12.00 7 10.42 12.65 340 Debt ratio .8071 2.138 5.564 .8938 3.377 22.82 314 Investment .0551 .1510 .8979 .578 .0883 .1033 284 Investment96 .0482 .0882 .161 1 .0545 .0826 .0823 317 Cash flow .0798 .0766 1.260 .0848 .0084 .8823 297 Cash flow 96 .0779 -.0162 .5555 .0850 .0131 .3651 331 EBIT .0880 .1097 1.584 .0815 .0378 .6947 306 ROA .0387 -.0185 .664 .0314 -.0435 .8696 306 Dividend 0 .0144 .148 0 -.0136 .885 355 Note - * different mean or median significant at the 10% level ** different mean or median significant at the 5% level *** different mean or median significant at the 1% level **** different mean or median significant at the 0.5% level ***** different mean or median significant at the 0.1% level 86 .EazquU E 2.6 3383 Odom w:_mm_E 95 3.6 9:883; wEmflE 2: 9 26 8:6: 2 mcozaioms: mo 52:5: 2: -202 2 mcocetomno 87 3mm moi 23¢ a2: 33 053 Owen 2 mm m0 89:52 3:. 3:. emom. avZ. 0&2. 2.2. :2. .39 «m 83.8 95va 638.8 Amwmfiv 83.8 2358 Avoodv $3.9 C m.m wom.m god mood ovmd mm: .m EON 2 .wm 385:: 3:556 ovco x326:— mo> wo> mo> mot» mo> m»; mm; mm; :wfié 3089 momcoaxm 8%. @5223. 22E 28.0 8225 *****mo.v *****mo._ Odom 38.8 23.: SON: $5.8 Goody ammdv **voo._ mac; two.— ****O©o._ **moo._ ****wmv._ Emu Song; 600.: 8&3; $60.7v Amwm._-v §VN4¢ amorv 929$ 83 .- *ommmr 1.33.- ... _ mmmr o3: .- wag: Soon N38 Aowfiwoq $00.4; Amnog¢ 33¢ Qrch¢ Amoo.m-v Scowd; Ao— Zl Suwv *****Nm_.- **wOZr 2N6: **m_N_.- ***...xbgr NON—r *****m—_.- *****w\r.o- Aofimvwoi— 2 :31 :33 ENE 33 2.2: 33.1 *****wm._- *****Ov._- mg.— 0500. 350.. *****ON._- 2m Am _ wrv ammo... ZOE.883 $20 :26 so a FEDS. Co .5693on 225:8» $8? 802 88 Table B9. Cross Sectional Regressions of Q in 1995: Subsample with Only The Dual Class Firms Have Both Classes Traded Publicly Note —cross sectional regression of Tobin’s q on dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent variables and summary statistics Subsample with only dual class firms have both classes traded publicly DUAL 2.653 -4.112** -.8473* (0.362) (- l .773) (1.677) VOTE -4.112** -7.290** (-2. 167) (-2.366) CASH -. 1829 2.699 5.847* (-.380) (1.384) (1.836) VOTE.0tolO —6.642 (-1.411) VOTE.over10 -7.295** (-2.359) CASH.Oto75 5754* (1.791) CASH.over75 7.327 (.924) Log(size) -6.75***** -.111***** -0211 -.13***** -.1193* -.1175* (-7.7) (-4.07) (-.397) (-3.81) (-1.939) (-1.773) Log(age) 7.412 -. 198 —.269* -.148 -.3155 -.311 (2.018) (-1.246) (-1.837) (-l.268) (- l .586) (-1.543) Fstd l.43**** 9753* 1.406 1.380 (2.913) (1.837) (1.109) (.983) R&D 1.94***** 4.20***** 4.20***** (3.60) (7.63) (7.60) Advertising .3239 (.323) 4-digit Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes code dummies Intercept 28.13 2.628 2.906 3.295 3.603 3.552 (5.998) (11.85) (6.334) (8.916) (5.226) (4.288) R2 .0681 .2503 .5100 .1326 .1311 .1295 Number of 5715 3480 474 2443 1406 1406 observations '~I|.- g -_l\_‘- r. shill-$5211, 5. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 89 Table BIO. Cross Sectional Regressions of Q in 1995: Subsample of Firms in Media Industries and Firms in Non-media Industries Note —cross sectional regression of Tobin’s q on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t- statistics are in parentheses. Independent Subsample 0f Subsample of Subsample of Subsample of Subsample of variables and firms in media firms in media firms in media firms in non- firms in non- summary industries industries industries media media industries statistics industries DUAL -.234 -.217 -.360* -.6334* E (-.873) (-731) (-1.824) (-1.635) T VOTE -.488 E (-.459) 5; CASH -l.05* -.659 -.0368 (-l.778) (-500) (-.O78) ; Log(size) -.0092 -.0065 -.0575 -.123***** -.00137 i (-. 145) (-.093) (-.825) (4255) (-.027) Log(age) —.262 -.424* -.456 -.0824 -.2403* (-1.158) (-l.736) (-1.822) (-.8l6) (-l.647) Fstd .498 .300 -.513 1.437**** (.258) (.149) (-.251) (2.855) R&D Expense l.945***** (3.637) Advertising .372 Expense (.383) 4-digit Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes code dummies Intercept 2.52 3.249 3.781 2.712 2.722***** (3.172) (3.869) (4.277) (8.754) (6.036) R2 .0729 .1319 .0162 .1527 .5050 Number of 156 126 123 4125 492” observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level '4 Note- the number of the observations is limited due to the missing R&D Expense and Advertising Expense data in Compustat. 90 Table B11. Regressions of Market-to-book Equity Ratio Note —cross sectional regression of market-to-book equity ratio on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent variables Full Subsample of Subsample Subsample of and summary sample firms that have of firms in dual class statistics both classes media firms only traded publicly industries l' ; VOTE . -l .825 -.2221 -4.332 .9589 .i - (-.506) (-025) (-.630) (.448) ' CASH .5059 -1.066 1.466 - l .782 (.127) (-. 1 16) (.186) (-.614) ~. Log(size) -.0624 -.05600 -.4997 .1653 ‘ (-.403) (—.344) (— l .530) (.543) Log(age) -.7016 -.7855 -2.421** .00607 (-1 .323) {-1.412) (-2.229) (.010) Fstd 5.464** 5.316 (2.148) (2.033) 4-digit Industry code Yes Yes Yes Yes dummies Intercept 5.213 5.448 ’ 13.73 1.598 (3.117) (3.131) (4.582) (.645) R2 .1852 .2969 .0715 -.3081 Number of 2955 2836 235 235 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 91 Table B12. Regressions of Price/Earnings Ratio Note —cross sectional regression of Price/Earnings ratio on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent Full Full sample Subsample of Subsample Subsample variables and sample firm that of firms in of dual summary have both media class firms statistics classes traded industries only publicly VOTE -24.14 -47. 10* -87.59 -174.1 4.741 (—1.281) (-l.687) (-1.227) (-.873) (.191) CASH 26.25 60.10** 104.23 120.3 -.6276 (1.261) (2.020) (1.443) (.511) (-.018) Log(size) 1.690** 4.853***** 5.298***** 7.874 -4.533 (2.097) (5.109) (5.389) (.774) (- 1 .222) Log(age) 5031* -4.324* -4.757* -24.96 -3.309 (1.823) (-l.689) (-1.800) (-.766) (-.452) Fstd -2.310 (-. 174) Tobin’s Q .4477 ** .4532** 2.919 -l.664 (2.075) (2.069) (.623) (-.537) 4-di git Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes code dummies Intercept -l.903 9.692 8.010 79.79 54.47 (-.219) (1.212) (.970) (.853) (1.750) R2 —.0137 0 .0051 -.0557 -4572 Number of 5369 4623 4471 224 217 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level Table B13. Regressions of ROA Note —cross sectional regression of ROA (return on assets) on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent Full sample Full sample Full sample Subsample of Subsample of variables and dual class firms dual class firms summary statistics only only Dual class dummy -.0375 (-1.083) E VOTE -.1544 -.1130 1: (-.l 17) (-1.546) . VOTE.0t05 2.043*** 11.19* E. (2.590) (1.889) VOTE.5to25 -.O701 -2.536* "_ (-.358) (-2.017) ‘3 VOTE.over25 -.2085 -.0816 (-1.483) (-.3l6) CASH .0818 .2374 .2108 .2346** .5193 (2.007) (1.598) (1.403) (2.37) (1.546) Log(size) .0428***** .0429***** .0484***** .0239* .0694 (9.615) (9.582) (10.167) (1.799) (1.616) Log(age) .0048 .0053 .00815 .0413 .136* (.380) ( .420) (.640) (1.371) (1.909) Fstd -1.521***** (3.946) Lagged Tobin’s q -.0259***** -.0258 -.0255***** .0086 .0393 (-7.076) (-7.039) {-6.967) (.482) (.0942) R&D Expense -1.340***** - 1 .400 -l.400***** -l.494** (-48.6) (-7.039) (-48.56) (-2.481) 4-digit Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes code dummies Intercept -.0703 -.0726 -.203 -.0985 -.953 (-1.791) (-l.83 1) (-3.583) (-3.946) (~2.343) R2 .7491 .7048 .7062 .3538 .2781 Number of 2303 2292 2292 156 102 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 93 Table B14. Regressions of EBIT Note —cross sectional regression of EBIT/Assets on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t- statistics are in parentheses. Independent Full sample Full sample Full sample Subsample Subsample Subsample variables and of dual of dual of dual summary class firms class firms class firms statistics only only only Dual class -.0598 dummy (-1.709) VOTE -.2199 -.139 -.l66 (-l.576) (-1.408) (-.755) VOTEOIOS 2.237**** 10.34* (2.811) (1.809) VOTE.5t025 -.l70 -2.26* (-.082) (-1.865) VOTE.over25 -.271* -.102 (-l.909) (-.410) CASH .0592 .278* .257* .221 .423 .438 (1.440) (1.859) (1.698) (1.615) (1.259) (1.353) Log(size) .0557 .0556***** .0614***** .0523***** .0622* .0594 (12.40) (12.32) (12.80) (3.527) (1.725) (1.434) Log(age) -.0134 -.0129 -.0098 .0425 .0773 .0885 (-l.048) (-1.002) (-.761) (1.333) (1.140) (1.289) Lagged -.0289***** -.029***** -.028***** .0444“ .0732* .0408 Tobin’s q (-7.825) (-7.781) (-7.698) (2.144) (1.955) (1.015) R&D Expense -1.347 -l.35***** -l.35***** -1.834**** -1.756*** (-46.381) (-46.26) (-46.34) (-3.134) (-3.022) 4-digit Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Industry code dummies Intercept —.0153 -.Ol70 -. 159 -.401 -.572 -.691 (-.387) (-.425) (-2.78) (-3.003) (-l.579) (-l .760) R2 .6978 .6976 .6992 .2168 .3058 .3553 Number of 2303 2292 2292 204 102 102 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 94 Table B15. Regressions of Operating Cash Flow Note —cross sectional regression of Operating cash Flow/Assets on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent Full sample Full sample Full sample variables and summary statistics Dual class dummy -.0452 (-1.314) VOTE -. 171 (-1.248) VOTE.0t05 2.10*** (2.690) VOTE.51025 -. 142 (-.730) VOTE.over25 -.214 (-l.539) CASH .0945** 266* .249* (2.341) (1.809) (1.675) Log(SIZC) _044***** .044***** .O49***** (9.995) (9.952) (10.47) Log(age) .00305 .0036 .0065 (.243) (.288) (.515) Fstd Lagged Tobin's q -.026***** -.026***** -.025***** (-7.075) (-7.04) (-6.951) R&D Expense -1.38***** -1.38***** -l.38***** (-48.35) (48.24) (-48.30) 4-di git Industry code Yes Yes Yes dummies Intercept -.0226 -.0247 -. 154 (-.05 8) (-.629) (-2.751) R2 .7024 .7022 .7483 Number of 2298 2288 2288 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 95 Table B15. (Continued) Regressions of Operating Cash Flow Note —cross sectional regression of Operating cash Flow/Assets on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. Independent Subsample Subsample Subsample Subsample of variables and of dual class of dual class of dual class dual class summary firms only firms only firms only firms only statistics VOTE -.151 -.184 -.l33* F‘ (-1.496) (-.808) (-1.699) 3 .f VOTE.0t05 11.01 * .9 (1.878) VOTE.5t025 -2.549* (-2.050) VOTE.over25 -.0916 (-.359) . ‘ CASH .221 .473 .251** .488 i (1.592) (1.358) (2.331) (1.469) Log(size) .044**** .0700* 0258* .0629 (2.92) (1.872) (1.808) (1.480) Log(age) .0518 .121 .027 .136* (1.624) (1.715) (.835) (1.937) Fstd -1.37***** (3.312) Lagged Tobin’s q .0296 0733* .0073 .390 (1.406) (1.890) (.382) ( .946) R&D Expense -1.68** -1.618** (-2.77) (—2.715) 4-digit Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes code dummies Intercept -.350 -.740 -.0207 -.840 (~2.570) (- l .97) (-. 135) (-2.086) R2 .2539 .2651 .4264 .3322 Number of 203 102 156 102 observations * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 96 Table B16. Cross Sectional Regressions of DIVIDEND in 1995 Independent Sub Sub Sub Sub Subsample Sub Subsample variables -sample of -sample of -sample of -sample of of firms in -sample of of firms in and firms in firms in firms in firms in media firms in non-media summary media media media media industries non-media industries statistics industries industries industries industries industries DUAL -.028***** -.0007 dummy (-3.846) (-.068) VOTE -.070**** -.O70**** -.070**** -.073**** -.00186 (-2.981) (2969) (-2.98) (-2.664) (-.057) CASH .05 34* .0530* 0533* 0620* -.00505 (1.925) (1.909) (1.923) (1.913) (-.l47) Log(SlZC) _007***** .OO7***** “m7***** .009***** .009***** .00283101‘ .003***** (5.701) (5.660) (5.77) (6.49) (7.14) (2.521) (-4.03) Log(age) .020***** .020***** .020***** .021***** .016***** .Ol4***** __009***** (5.020) (5.014) (5.059) (4.695) (3.93) (4.271) (-3.34) EBIT m.00271 (-.515) CSHFLO -.00268 -.0033 -.00028 .00002 .000382 (-.6l7) (-.666) (-.057) (.138) (.491) NET -.00389 INCOME (-.851) Tobin Q .00188** (2.109) PE ratio -3.6e-06 (-.384) Liquid .Ol 12 (1.205) 2-digit SIC Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes code Intercept -.0570 -.0570 -.0583 -.0713 -.0542 -.0260 -.Ol70 (-5.070) (-5.036) (-5.093) (-5.089) (-5.276) (-2.928) (-1.958) R2 .3390 .3387 .3400 .4047 .2283 .026 .04 Number of 229 229 229 176 345 6355 4578 observation Note -cross sectional regression of DIVENDEND on the dual class dummy variable, Separation index or insider voting rights and cash flow rights and control variables. DIVIDEND is defined as Cash Dividend/Total Equity Capital. t-statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level 97 my APPENDIX C APPENDIX FOR CHAPTER 3: DUAL-CLASS STOCK, INVESTNIENT AND CASH FLOW _9OI.'H'I 1:! . r v i ‘ S I! : i 98 Table C1. Investment Regression Results Independent variables Full sample Full sample Subsample Subsample of and summary statistics of dual dual class class firms firms Sales growth_l .000337 .00024 .000894 .0141 (.851) (.590) (.303) (1.214) Tobin’s q_1 .0067***** .0108***** .00767 0135* (7.542) (9.493) (.901) (1.742) Cash flow .0149***** .02805***** .06169 -.0284 (3.552) (3.322) (.744) (-.374) Cashflow*Voteright .1215 -.5297*** (.792) (-2.822) Cashflow*Cash —.l698 l.291***** (-1.091) (6.364) 4-di git SIC code Yes Yes Yes Yes Intercept .0685 .0604 .0705 .0498 (27.717) (20.399) (4.730) (4.507) R2 .2245 .2504 .6006 .9146 Number of observation 5766 4494 300 196 Note —cross sectional regression of Investment/Asset on cash flow, interaction term of cash flow and insider ownership of voting rights and interaction term of cash flow and insider ownership of cash flow rights, and control variables. t-statistics are in parentheses. * Significant at the 10% level ** Significant at the 5% level ***Significant at the 1% level ****Significant at the 0.5% level *****Significant at the 0.1% level or lower 99 BIBLOGRAPHY 100 BIBLOGRAPHY Amihud, Yakov and Baruch Lev, 1981, Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers, Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 2, 605-617 Anderson, Ronald C., and D. Scott Lee, 1997, Ownership Studies: The data Source Does matter, Journal of financial and Quantitative Analysis, 32, 3, 311-329 Ang, J .S. and Megginson, W.L.,1989, Restricted Voting Shares, Ownership Structure, and the Market Value of Dual-class Firms, Journal of Financial Research, 12, 301-318 Attari M., Bannerjee S., 1999, The Investment Decision and Dual Class Shares, working paper, University of Iowa Barclay, M. J., and CG. Holdemess, 1989, Private Benefits from Control of Public Corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 1989, 371-95 Berger, Philip (3., Eli Ofek, and David L. Yermack, 1997, Managerial Entrenchment and Capital Structure Decisions, Journal of Finance, 52, 4, 1411-1438 Bergstrém, C., Rydqvist, K., 1990, Ownership of Equity in Dual-class Firms, Journal of Banking and Finance, 14, 225-69 Berle, Adolf A., and Means, Gardiner C, The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan, 1932 Bohemer E., Sanger G., Varshney S., 1996, The Effect of consolidated control on firm performance: the Case of Dual-class IPOs. Empirical Issue in Raising Capital, Elservier. Caramanolis, Birgul, Rajina Gibson and Nils S. Tuchschmid, 1996, Dual Class Shares Firms and Seasoned Equity Offerings: Empirical Evidence form the Swiss Stock Mar. :1. Empirical Issue in Raising Capital, Elservier Chang, S. and D. Mayers, 1992, Managerial Vote Ownership and Shareholder Wealth, Journal of Financial Economics, 32, 103-131 Comment Robert, G. William Schwert, 1995, Poison or placebo? Evidence on the deterrence and wealth effects of modern antitakover measures, Journal of Financial Economics, 39, 3-43 Comett Marcia Million, Michael R. Vetsuypens, 1989, Voting Rights and Shareholder Wealth: The issuance of limited Voting common stock, Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 10, 175-188 101 DeAngelo, H. and DeAngelo, L., 1985, Managerial Ownership of Voting Rights - A Study of Public Corporations with Dual Classes of Common Stock, Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 33-69 Demsetz, Harold, Kenneth Lehn, 1985,The Structure of Coporate Ownership: Causes and consequences, Journal of Political Economy, 93,1 155-1 177 Denis D., Denis D., 1994, Majority Owner-managers and Organizational Efficiency, Journal of Corporate Finance, 1, 91-118 Dybvig, PH. and Zender, J .F., 1991, Capital Structure and Dividend Irrelevance with Asymmetric Information, Review of Financial Studies, 4, 201-219 Fazzari, S.M., Hubbard, R.G., and Peterson, BC, 1988, Financiang Constraints and Corporate Investment, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity, 141-195 Fischel D., 1987, Organized Exchange and the Regulation of Dual Class Common Stock, Chicago Law Review, 54, 119-52 Foster, Stephen R., David C. Porter, 1993, Dual Class Shares: Are There Returns Differences?, Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 20(6), November, 893—903 Gompers, Paul A., Joy L. Ishii and Andrew Metrick, 2001, Corporate Governance and Equity ‘ Prices, working paper, Harvard university, University of Pennsylvania and NBER Greenwald, B., Stiglitz, IE, and Weiss, A., 1984, Information Imperfections in the Capital Market and Macroeconomic Fluctuations, American Economic Review, 74, 194-199 Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver D. Hart, 1988, One Share / One Vote and the Market for Corporate Control, Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 175-202 Grullon, Gustavo, and George Kantas, 2001, Managerial Incentives, Capital Structure, and Firm Value: Evidence from Dual-Class Stocks, working paper, Rice University Hadlock, Charles J., 1998, Ownership, Liquidity, and Investment, RAND Journal of Economics, 29, No. 3, 487-508 Harris, Milton and Artur Raviv, 1988, Corporate Governance: Voting Rights and Majority Rules, Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 203-235 Homer, M.R., (1988), The Value of the Corporate Voting Right - Evidence from Switzerland, Journal of Banking and Finance, 12, 69-83 J arrell, Gregg A., Annette B. Poulsen, 1988, Dual-class Recapitalizations as Antitakeover Mechanisms — the Recent Evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 129-152 Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers, American Economic Review, 76, 323-329 Jog, V. M., Riding, A.L., (1986), Price Effects of Dual-class Shares, Financial Analysts Journal, 86 (Jan/Feb), 58-66 Kaplan, Steven N., and Luigi Zingales, 1997, Do Investment-cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 169-216 Lamont, Owen, 1997, Cash Flow and Investment: Evidence From Internal Capital Markets, Joumal of Finance, 52, 83-110 Kunz, Roger, M., James J. Angel, 1996, Factors Affecting the Value of the Stock Voting Right: Evidence from the Swiss Equity Market, Financial Management, Vol. 25, 3, autumn, 7-20 Lease, Ronald C., John J. McConnell and Wayne H. Mikkelson, 1983, The Market Value of Control in Publicly Traded Corporations, Journal of Financial Economics, April, 439-472 Lease, Ronald C., John J. McConnell and Wayne H. Mikkelson, 1984, The Market Value of Differential Voting Rights in Closely Held Corporations, Journal of Business, October, 443- 467 Lehn, Kenneth, Jeffry Netter and Annette Poulson, 1990, Consolidating Corporate Control: Dual-class recapitalizations versus Leveraged Buyouts, Journal of Financial Economics, 27, 557-80 Levy, H., (1983), Economic Evaluation of Voting Power of Common Stock, Joumal of Finance, 38, 79-93 Liljeblom, E., and Rydqvist, K., 1992, Wealth Effects of Dual-class Shares - An Empirical Study on Swedish Data, unpublished manuscript, Stockholm School of Economics Myers, S.C., and Majluf, NS, 1984, Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not have, Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187-221 Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny, 1988, Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293-315 103 Nicodano, Giovanna, 1998, Corporate Groups, Dual-class Shares and the Value of Voting Rights, Journal of Banking & Finance 22, 1117-37 Olrog, C., and Rickhamre, KG, 1992, F éretagskép idetframtidaEuropa, SNS Publishing Company, Stockholm Palepu, Krishna G., 1986, Predicting Takeover Targets: a Methodological and Empirical Analysis, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 8, 3-35 Partch, M. Megan, 1987, The Creation of a class of Limited Voting Common Stock and Shareholder Wealth, Journal of Financial Economics, 18, 313-39 Perfect, Steven B., and Kenneth W. Wiles, 1994, Alternative Construction of Tobin’s q: An Empirical Comparison, Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 313-341 Robinson, C., White, A., 1990, The Value of a Vote in the Market for Corporate Control, unpublished manuscript, York University Rydqvist, Kristian, 1993, Dual-class Shares: A Review, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 8, No. 3, 45-57 Ruback R., 1988, Coercive dual-class exchange offers, Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 153 -173 Shin, Hyun-Han, and Rene M. Stulz, 1998, Are Internal Capital Markets Efficient?, Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 531-552 Shin, Hyun-Han, and Rene M. Stulz, 2000, Firm Value, Risk, and growth opportunities, NBER working paper #7808 Smart, Scott 3., Chad J. Zutter, 2000,Control As a motivation for Underpricing: A Comparison of Dual- and Single- Class IPOs, August, Working paper, Indiana University Shum, Connie M., Wallace N. Davidson and John L. Glascock, 1995, Voting Rights and Market Reaction to Dual Class Common Stock Issues. Financial Review 30, 275-87 Stulz, Rene M., 1988, Managerial Control of Voting Rights: Financing Policies and the Market for Corporate Control, Journal of Financial Economics, J anuary/March, 25-54 , 1990, Managerial Discretions and Optimal Financing Policies, Journal of Financial Economics, 26, 3-27 Taylor S., Whittred G., 1998, Security Design and the Allocation of Voting Rights: Evidence From the Australian IPO Market, Journal of Corporate Finance 4, 107-31 104 Wooldridge, Jeffrey, M., 1999. Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, South- Westem College Publishing Zingales, L., 1994, The Value of the Voting Rights: A study of the Milan Stock Exchange Experience, Review of Financial Studies, VII (1994), 125—48 , 1995, What determines the Value of Corporate Votes?, Quarterly Journal of Economics, November, 1047-73 105 IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII llnllflll11111111Mllllzlllfllfllfilll