LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MAR 1 I 2005 331;; as 6/01 c:/CIRC/DateDue.p65-p. 15 THE INTERNATIONAL SPILLOVER EFFECTS OF US. TAX REFORM: A COMPUTATIONAL GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH WITH A GLOBAL TRADE MODEL By Kiwon Kang A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2002 ABSTRACT THE INTERNATIONAL SPILLOVER EFFECTS OF U.S. TAX REFORM: A COMPUTATIONAL GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH WITH A GLOBAL TRADE MODEL By Kiwon Kang I integrate trade modeling and tax modeling, by evaluating the international spillover effects of changes in U.S. tax policy. I use both static and dynamic computational general-equilibrium models that divide the world into four regions. The data are from Global Trade Analysis Project for 1995. My model incorporates a labor/leisure choice and international cross-ownership of assets. My simulations suggest that unilateral elimination of U.S. capital taxes generates capital inflows. This policy change encourages more efficient use of the capital stock, but it will also generate negative effects on the terms of trade. Overall, the policy change generates welfare gains for the United States. If the other regions do not respond to the U.S. policy change, they suffer welfare losses. However, if all regions eliminate capital taxes, welfare gains accrue for the entire world. The analysis of welfare gains for the United States indicates that unilateral elimination of U.S. capital taxes yields an annual static welfare gain of around $98 billion in 1995 dollars (which amounts to 1.4 percent of GDP), while it yields dynamic gains, whose present values are around $4.0~$4.1 trillion (which amount to 2.2 percent of GDP stream). Copyright by Kiwon Kang 2002 Dedicated to My father, Dong-Hyuk Kang My mother, Young-Nam Kim My mother-in-law, Myung-J a Jung My wife, Chooyoung Lee My daughter, Michelle Kang iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The work with this dissertation has been long and extensive. Without support and encouragement from several people, this work could not have been accomplished. First of all, I would like to express my sincerest gratitude to my advisor, Dr. Charles L. Ballard. He has taught me innumerable lessons and guided my research in the right direction. He also provided me deeper understanding of economics. His expert guidance was essential to the completion of this dissertation. I also would like to thank to all committee members, including Dr. John H. Goddeeris and Dr. Lawrence W. Martin, for their invaluable commentary. I also would like to give special thanks to Dr. Gill Chin Lim for his unconditional understanding and support throughout my graduate studies in East Lansing. He has always showed me his energy and enthusiasm. His genuine efforts will influence the rest of my life. Thanks also go out to all my friends at the Department of Economics (especially, room 4 in the Old Botany) and the Visiting International Professional Program, Michigan State University. Last, but not least, I would like to thank my family for their endless love and support. I especially owe much to my parents for their dedication and patience. My wife, Chooyoung, deserves to receive my deepest appreciation. Her love and devotion itself was, in the end, what made this dissertation possible. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................ vii LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................... ix CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION ...................................................... 1 CHAPTER 2. RELEVANT STUDIES ................................................ 4 2.1. The Incidence of the Corporate Tax ............................................. 4 2.2. Efficiency Results from Simulation Models .................................... 6 CHAPTER 3. DESCRIPTION OF THE SIMULATION MODEL ............ 13 3.1. Overview ........................................................................... 13 3.2. Structure of the Static Model .................................................... 18 CHAPTER 4. MODEL CALIBRATION ............................................ 41 4.1. Exogenous Parameters ........................................................... 41 4.2. Calibration Issues ................................................................. 43 CHAPTER 5. DATA AND SIMULATION METHOD .......................... 57 5.1. Data Interpretation ............................................................... 57 5.2. Simulation Method ............................................................... 69 CHAPTER 6. SIMULATION RESULTS IN THE STATIC CASE ........... 70 6.1. Central-Case Simulation ......................................................... 70 6.2. Sensitivity Analyses .............................................................. 83 6.3. Alternative Scenarios ............................................................ 95 CHAPTER 7. DYNAMIC MODEL ................................................. 103 7.1. Model and Calibration Issues .................................................. 103 7.2. Simulation Results .............................................................. 109 CHAPTER 8. CONCLUSION ....................................................... 122 APPENDIX ........................................................................................ 124 BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................... 139 vi Table 4-1. Table 4-2. Table 4-3. Table 4-4. Table 4-5. Table 5-1. Table 5-2. Table 5-3. Table 5-4. Table 5-5. Table 5-6. Table 5-7 Table 5-8. Table 5-9. Table 6-1. Table 6-2. Table 6-3. Table 6-4. Table 6-5. Table 6-6 Table 6—7. Table 6-8. Table 6-9. LIST OF TABLES Exogenous Parameter Values ....................................................... 43 Calibrated Parameter Values ........................................................ 46 Elasticity of Capital Abroad and Calibrated Asset-Substitution Elasticity ...50 Price Elasticities of Import Demand and Calibrated Trade Elasticity of Substitution ............................................................................ 55 The SALTER Trade Elasticities .................................................... 56 Levels of Economic Activity by Region .......................................... 57 Dataset Mapping of Regions from GTAP version 4 ............................. 58 Dataset Mapping of Sectors from GTAP version 4 .............................. 59 Factor Taxes in the Model ........................................................... 61 Capital Taxes in EU. ................................................................. 64 Consumption Tax Rates in the Model ............................................. 65 Import Tariffs by Sector ............................................................ 66 Total Value of Imports and Exports by Sector and Region ...................... 67 Bilateral Trade Flows by Sector .................................................... 68 Possible Effects of Reducing U.S. Capital Taxes ................................. 73 Effects on Capital Flows ............................................................ 74 Effects on the Terms of Trade ...................................................... 75 Domestic Effects of the Tax-Policy Change on the U.S. Economy ............ 77 Spillover Effects of the U.S. Tax-Policy Change on Foreign Economics .....79 U.S. Static Welfare Changes of Unilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters ............................................... 81 Decomposing the Static EVs ......................................................... 82 Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Imported Goods I ......................................... 84 Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Imported Good II ......................................... 85 Table 6—10.Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution among Different Imported Goods I ................................................. 88 vii LIST OF TABLES (cont’d) Table 6-11. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution among Different Imported Goods II ............................................... 89 Table 6-12. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Different Combinations of Trade Elasticities of Substitution .......................................................... 90 Table 6-13. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Asset-Substitution Elasticities .....93 Table 6-14. Domestic Effects of Non-Zero Equalization of U.S. Capital Taxes ........... 97 Table 6-15. Domestic Effects of U.S. Labor-Tax Replacement ............................. 98 Table 6-16. Sensitivity Analyses with Different Combinations of Labor-Supply Elasticities and Goods Elasticity of Substitution ................................ 99 Table 6-17. U.S. Static Welfare Changes of Multilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters .............................................. 102 Table 7-1. The Impact and Long-Run Effects of Replacing of U.S. Capital Taxes ...112 Table 7-2. The Equivalent Variation I - Dynamic Simulation of Unilateral Case ......116 Table 7-3. The Equivalent Variation II - Dynamic Simulation of Unilateral Case .....117 Table 7-4. The Equivalent Variation III - Dynamic Simulation of Multilateral Case ..117 Table 7-5. The Equivalent Variation IV - Dynamic Simulation of Multilateral Case ..118 Table 7-6. U.S. Dynamic Welfare Changes of Unilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters .............................................. 118 Table 7-7. U.S. Dynamic Welfare Changes of Multilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters .............................................. 119 Table 7-8. Intertemporal Effects for the U.S. ................................................ 120 Table 7-9. Welfare Effects for Whole World ................................................ 120 viii Figure 3-1. Figure 3-2. Figure 6-1. Figure 6-2. Figure 6—3. Figure 6-4. Figure 6-5. Figure 7-1. Figure 7-2. Figure 7-3. Figure 7-4. Figure 7-5. Figure 7-6. Figure 7-7. LIST OF FIGURES The Structure of the Production ................................................... 17 The Structure of Utility ............................................................. 24 Terms-of-Trade Effects from Elimination of U.S. Capital Taxes, As a Function of the Elasticity of Substitution Between Domestic and Imported Goods ..................................................................... 86 Capital-Flow Effects from Elimination of U.S. Capital Taxes, As a Function of the Elasticity of Substitution Between Domestic and Foreign Assets ................................................................................. 92 Welfare Gains for the U.S. from Unilateral Elimination of Capital Taxes, As a Function of Labor-Supply Elasticity ........................................ 95 Optimal Strategy for the United States ........................................... 96 Welfare Effects - Unilateral vs. Multilateral ................................... 101 Consumption Path - All Regions ................................................. 109 Leisure Path - All Regions ........................................................ 110 Utility Path - All Regions ......................................................... 110 Consumption Path - U.S. .......................................................... 112 Leisure Path - U.S. ................................................................. 113 Utility Path - U.S. .................................................................. 114 U.S. Consumption Path, As a Function of Savings Elasticity . . . . . . . . . 1 14 ix CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION The current tax-reform debate in the United States has focused attention on proposals that would lead to reform of the taxation of capital income. In the current debates, three proposals have received the most attention; the “flat tax” proposal, which suggests cutting income-tax rates to a single rate, the “unlimited saving allowance” proposal, which suggests providing deductions for all savings, and the “consumption-tax- only” proposal, which asserts complete replacement of the federal income tax with a value-added tax.1 Although they differ in some important details, each of these proposals points toward reduced taxation of capital income generally (and corporate capital income in particular), and toward increased consumption taxation. Much of the discussion has focused on the effect of tax reforms on labor supply and capital accumulation within the domestic economy. A number of authors have simulated the effects of moving toward consumption taxation in closed-economy models, and have generally found that heavier reliance on consumption taxation will lead to welfare gains in the long run.2 International issues have been given relatively little attention. However, as the world economy becomes increasingly integrated, it becomes increasingly appropriate to focus on international issues. Recently, some researchers have begun to study the 1 See the papers in Mieszkowski and Zodrow (forthcoming, 2002), which discuss the effects of various proposals that would move in the direction of greater reliance on consumption taxation. 2 These papers include Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1983), Fullerton, Shoven, and Whalley (1983), Ballard (1990a), Auerbach, Kotlikoff, Smetters, and Walliser (1997), Engen and Gale (1997), Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1997), Rogers (1997), and Altig, Auerbach, Kotlikoff, Smetters, and Walliser (2001). international implications of major tax reforms. In the early 19803, Whalley (1980) and Goulder, Shoven, and Whalley (1983) analyze the effects of tax-policy changes, using open-economy simulation models. More recently, in the 19903, Grubert and Newlon (1995), Hines (1996), Thalrnann, Goulder, and DeLorme (1996), and Mendoza and Tesar (1998) deal with the international considerations of tax reform. Multi-region models, in which international trade is the key inter-regional link, have been developed for analyzing global issues, especially multilateral trade policy issues such as trade liberalization, other trade policies, or fiscal policies that may be changed simultaneously in a number of countries.3 With an integrated world market for goods, the effects of tax policies undertaken by a single country spill over to other countries. Recognition of such international economic interdependence stimulates interest in the international coordination of fiscal policies, in general, and of tax reforms, in particular. My study aims to integrate tax and trade issues, by evaluating the international spillover effects of U.S. fimdamental tax reform, and examining the key elements determining the magnitude of its effects, using a multi-region trade model. In this study, international spillover effects, through both changes in commodity flows and changes in capital flows, are considered. This paper begins with a description of previous studies, which are summarized in Chapter 2. Chapter 3 describes the static simulation model, which is mainly used for the analyses. Chapter 4 provides the model calibration. The 3 In the middle of the 19905, Hertel and Tsigas (1996) developed the standard GTAP, which is well suited for analyzing the effects of trade policies. There have been a lot of studies that deal with trade issues, with multi-region trade models. However, there are only a few papers that analyze the effects of fiscal-policy changes, using multi-region trade models. Only a few works deal with both tax and trade issues simultaneously: Whalley (1980) focuses on the global effects of domestic factor-tax systems, and Whalley (1982) partly deals with tax policy, in addition to trade issues. data and simulation method are discussed in Chapter 5. Chapter 6 presents and interprets the simulation results in the static case. The issues on dynamic simulations are discussed in Chapter 7. Lastly, Chapter 8 concludes. CHAPTER 2 RELEVANT STUDIES 2.1. The Incidence of the Corporate Tax Harberger (1962) constructs a perfectly competitive, static, closed-economy model with two sectors and two factors of production. When a tax is levied on capital income in the corporate sector, competitive forces lead to a re-allocation of the capital stock. This re-allocation continues until the net-of—tax return to capital is the same in each sector. This leads to the result that the burden of the tax is borne by all capital, including capital that is not located in the corporate sector. The results of Harberger’s model depend on the elasticities of substitution between capital and labor in the two sectors, the elasticities of demand for the two outputs, and the factor intensities in production. However, Harberger finds that his basic result is quite robust with respect to changes in the parameters of the model. Shoven (1976) extends the Harberger model to include 12 production sectors. Shoven’s model is more elaborate than that of Harberger, but it retains the basic character of the Harberger model by assuming perfect competition in a static context. Consequently, it is not surprising that Shoven’s results are broadly supportive of Harberger’s. However, the efficiency effects estimated by Shoven are larger than those estimated by Harberger. In effect, the assumption that there are only two sectors leads to an understatement of the intersectoral distortions caused by differential capital taxation. When Shoven moves to a 12-sector model, the simulated efficiency effects increase substantially. Fullerton, King, Shoven, and Whalley (FKSW, 1981) continue to assume perfect competition, and they continue to assume that there are no international capital flows. However, they extend the model to 19 production sectors, and they make the model dynamic. In the short to medium run, the results of FKSW are similar to those of Harberger (1962) and Shoven (1976): When the corporate and personal income taxes are integrated, the returns to capital increase throughout the economy. This implies that the burden of the corporate tax is borne by capital. However, when FKSW trace out the dynamic development of the economy, the incidence picture changes in dramatic fashion. When the rate of return to capital is increased by the integration of the corporate tax, the rate of capital accumulation is increased. Consequently, in the very long run, the capital stock is substantially larger when there is no corporate tax than it would have been in the presence of the corporate tax. This increased capital stock leads to higher real wage rates for workers, which means that labor bears a substantial portion of the burden of the corporate tax in the long run. All of the studies described above have assumed a closed economy.4 When international flows of goods and capital are allowed, the results can change significantly. Harberger (1995) considers a static, perfectly competitive model in which there are international flows of goods and capital. Harberger assumes that the world capital market functions perfectly, in spite of the evidence of substantial international capital immobility.5 For a small, open economy, the net-of—tax rate of return to capital is fixed in ‘ There have been many other studies of the quantitative effects of tax policy changes, using closed- economy models. These include Shoven and Whalley (1972), Whalley (1975), Keller (1980), Slernrod (1983), Piggott and Whalley (1985), and Ballard, Fullerton, Shoven, and Whalley (1985). 5 The evidence on international capital immobility is extensive. Feldstein and Horioka (1980) report empirical evidence suggesting that capital is quite immobile internationally. Frankel (1990) and Obstfeld (1993) provide a review of the literature that was spawned by F eldstein and Horioka. Several possible the world capital market. Consequently, there is no way for domestic capital to bear the burden of the tax. Instead, capital will flow out of the domestic economy, raising the domestic gross-of-tax rate of return to capital, until the net rate of return to domestic capital is once again equal to the net rate of return to capital in the rest of the world. When the international flow of goods is also perfectly competitive, the brunt of the corporate tax must be borne by domestic labor.6 Gravelle and Smetters (1998) build a model with imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign products, and imperfect portfolio substitution between domestic and foreign capital. Gravelle and Smetters find that these imperfections play an important role in limiting the amount of the corporate tax that is borne by domestic labor. In some cases, the burden on labor is eliminated entirely. Gravelle and Smetters perform a number of sensitivity analyses. Their results show a mild amount of sensitivity to changes in the parameters. However, for the parameter combinations that seem most reasonable, capital bears at least half of the burden of the tax, and often significantly more. 2.2. Efficiency Results from Simulation Models 2.2.1. Closed-Economy Simulation Models Among the many econometric studies of consumption functions, only a few suggest that saving is highly responsive with respect to the net-of-tax rate of return.7 explanations have been discussed in Gordon and Bovenberg (1996). Especially, Gordon and Bovenberg attribute international capital immobility to asymmetric information across countries. 6 Feldstein (1994) gives a similar argument. 7 One of the very few studies to find a really large elasticity is that of Taylor (1971). He finds elasticities in the vicinity of 0.8 to 0.9 in some cases. Another study is that of Heien (1972). Most studies find that the savings elasticity is not far fi'om zero, and some find that it is negative. Thus, if a simulation model implies that the savings elasticity is enormous, the results of the simulation study must be viewed with considerable caution. Unfortunately, many simulation models do imply very large savings elasticities. In a model that lacks uncertainty, or borrowing constraints, or any other rigidities, model consumers find it very easy to re-allocate their consumption across time, even though such re-allocations may be more difficult for real people in the real world. This problem is especially severe in models with very long time horizons. In the extreme case, a large number of researchers assume that consumers live forever. These infinite-horizon models often imply savings responses that are extremely unrealistic. Even in an overlapping- generations model, in which consumers live for a finite period, the problem can still be severe. For example, Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1983) show that simulations of the switch to a consumption tax involve an increase in the savings rate from 10 percent to 42 percent. This extreme result is driven by a feature that is common to the infinite-horizon models.8 In models of this type, the first step in the consumer’s decision-making process is to calculate his full wealth. This involves calculating the present discounted value of the infinite stream of the consumer’s labor time. For a fundamental tax reform, the net rate of return will usually increase. This means that the consumer’s full wealth will be smaller under the policy change than it was in the “base case”. Since the consumer is poorer, and since consumption in every period is a normal good, the consumer will want to reduce this first-period consumption. This can lead to a very large increase in saving, 8 See Ballard (1990a, 2001) for details. even if labor supply does not change. However, if the single-period utility function is a composite of consumption and leisure, the consumer will want to consume less leisure, in addition to consuming fewer goods. Therefore, the consumer will work more. When the consumer works more and consumes less, it is possible to have truly enormous increases in savings. Unfortunately, the workings of this type of model can tell us very little about what would actually happen in the real world, in response to a tax-policy change. In recent years, researchers have made promising developments in the specification of simulation models. Engen and Gale (1996, 1997) have developed overlapping-generations simulation models in which consumers are uncertain about their path of future earnings and their length of life. To a great extent, this uncertainty reduces the excessive sensitivity of savings. For example, Engen and Gale (1996) suggest that, if modeled within the context of a closed economy, fundamental tax reform would increase the U.S. saving rate by 0.3 to 0.8 percentage points. In these models, consumption is typically reduced in the first several years after the move to a consumption tax. However, the additional saving leads to a higher rate of capital accumulation, so that consumption is eventually higher under a consumption tax than an income tax. The present value of the gain in consumption in the future is usually large enough to outweigh the loss of consumption in the near term. Thus, virtually all of the closed-economy simulation studies find that movements toward consumption taxation would yield welfare improvements. Even though some of the simulation models imply that saving is extremely, unrealistically responsive, it does not necessarily follow that these models imply welfare improvements that are dramatically different from the welfare improvements that are simulated by models with more modest savings elasticities. As shown in Ballard (1990a), very large increases in the savings elasticity are ofien only associated with small increases in the simulated welfare gains from moving toward a consumption tax. With a small saving elasticity, consumption drops when a consumption tax is instituted, and then recovers. Consumption eventually approaches a new steady state, in which the level of consumption is higher than in the base case, but the rate of growth is the same. With a larger savings elasticity, consumption drops farther when a consumption tax is instituted, and it recovers more quickly. However, consumption will approach the same steady state for either value of the savings elasticity. Thus, the consumption profiles for the large- elasticity case and the small-elasticity case are really quite similar. For the large- elasticity case, consumption is lower at first, and then higher, and finally the levels of consumption in the two cases will converge to the same steady state. Consequently, the long-run welfare calculations may not be dramatically different. 2.2.2. Open-Economy Simulation Models Whalley (1980) evaluates the effects of removing domestic factor taxes, using a static trade model in which goods are mobile, but factors are immobile across regions, and suggests that the current factor tax structure can produce significant terms-of—trade gains. The result shows that significant welfare losses occur as a result of the elimination of domestic factor taxes. This result, which contrasts with the result of conventional closed-economy analysis, is explained by the fact that national terms-of—trade losses outweigh the gains from removal of domestic distortions. Goulder, Shoven, and Whalley (GSW, 1983) begin with the GEMTAP model, which they developed over a period of years, along with Ballard, Fullerton, and others.9 The standard version of the GEMTAP model has a very cursory treatment of the foreign sector, but GSW modify the GEMTAP model of the U.S. economy and tax system, to include international capital flows. Their results depend critically on whether a particular reform leads to an increase or a decrease in the net rate of return to capital in the United States, as perceived by foreign investors. For reforms that lead to an increase in this rate of return (such as corporate tax integration), the model suggests that the U.S. will receive capital inflows. As a result of these inflows of capital from abroad, the U.S. experiences significant welfare gains. The welfare gains are driven partly by international capital flows, which were ruled out by assumption in Whalley (1980). On the other hand, for reforms that lead to a decrease in the rate of return in the long run (such as an increase in the percentage of domestic saving that is taxed on a consumption-tax basis), the model usually finds that capital will flow out of the U.S., and these capital outflows lead to welfare losses. Even though the results are highly sensitive with respect to the values of elasticity parameters that control the degree of international capital flows, they demonstrate that our understanding of the effects of tax-policy changes may be altered when we introduce international capital flows. Thalrnann, Goulder, and DeLorme (1996) assess the effects on the U.S. economy of tax-policy changes in foreign countries. They use an infinite-horizon model that 9 For a detailed description of a standard version of the GEMTAP model, see Ballard, Fullerton, Shoven, and Whalley (1985). This model has the advantage that it can be calibrated to any desired savings elasticity so that it avoids some of the problems of excessive intertemporal responsiveness. 10 displays a larger degree of intertemporal sensitivity than does the model of GSW. However, their results are of some interest. For one thing, they explicitly incorporate imperfect substitutability between foreign and domestic assets, which is consistent with the econometric evidence on international capital mobility. Even for a fairly modest policy change (an increase in depreciation allowances in the rest of the world), the model of Thalrnann, et al., calculates a welfare improvement of 0.3 percent of GDP for the rest of the world. Mendoza and Tesar (1998) use a simulation model to assess the difference between the effects of fundamental tax reform in a closed economy and in an Open economy. Mendoza and Tesar employ some extreme assumptions. First, they use a model with an infinitely-lived consumer. As mentioned above, a model of this type is likely to produce simulated consumer behavior that is unrealistically responsive to changes in rates of return. Indeed, when Mendoza and Tesar simulate the effects of replacing the U.S. capital-income tax with a consumption tax in a closed-economy setting, they find that the impact effect is for consumption to decline by 8.3 percent, which seems extremely large and unrealistic. An infinite-horizon formulation tends to overstate intertemporal effects. The second extreme assumption is that they consider a world in which international capital markets are “fully integrated”; that is, capital is assumed to be perfectly mobile, in spite of the evidence of substantial international capital immobility. Thus, their simulations are likely to overstate the extent of the international capital flow that would be caused by fundamental tax reform in the United States. 11 Mendoza and Tesar suggest that the simulated welfare gains from replacing the U.S. capital-income tax with a consumption tax are greater when the simulations are carried out in an open-economy than in a closed-economy model. In the open-economy model, the U.S. gains by 2.89 percent, which is about one-third larger than in the closed- economy model. Although these earlier studies shed some light, they can be improved upon in several dimensions: (1) The papers mentioned above are based on models with only two regions. (2) The model of Mendoza and Tesar has a fully integrated world capital market, which greatly overstates the degree of international capital mobility. (3) The models of Thalrnann, et al., and Mendoza and Tesar employ infinite-horizon formulation, which tend to overstate the intertemporal effects of tax-policy changes. In this paper, I address some of these issues. The model described in the next section is a static model with four regions, in which capital is internationally mobile, but with incomplete adjustment in the world capital market. The model is extended later to the dynamic structure, which incorporates sequences of single-period equilibria. 12 CHAPTER 3 DESCRIPTION OF THE SIMULATION MODEL 3.1. Overview The basic framework for my research originates with the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP).lo The standard version of the GTAP model is a static, multi-sectoral, and multi-regional model, in which each region’s final demand is determined by a representative agent, who allocates expenditure across goods so as to maximize welfare. The model described here is based primarily on Rutherford’s (1998) GTAP-data-based CGE model.11 In some respects, the core model used here is essentially identical to the standard GTAP model. First, the model is static.12 There is no capital accumulation in the model. Consequently, in this version of the model, I may understate the distorting effects of capital taxes, since the effects on saving decisions are not captured.13 Second, perfect competition is assumed in all sectors and all regions. The production technology is 1° The Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) is a research program initiated in 1992 to provide the economic research community with a global economic data set for use in quantitative analyses of international economic issues. it The standard programming language for GTAP data and modeling work has been GEMPACK. In the GEMPACK framework (see Harrison and Pearson (1996)), the model is solved as a system of linearized equations. Rutherford (1998) develops a GTAP-data-based model that is implemented as a nonlinear complementarity problem in the GAMS programming language, and calls it the “GTAPinGAMS” model. The database represents global production and trade for 45 countries, 50 connnodities, and five primary factors. This database characterizes all transactions in 1995, and measures them in 1995 dollars. '2 The model described here has the same time frame as the well-known model of Harberger (1962), which is sometimes called a “medium-run” model. Since there is no capital accumulation, it is not a long-run model. However, it allows reallocation of the existing world capital stock among all sectors in the world. Thus, it is not a short-run model, either. '3 The dynamic version of the model, in which consumers make a saving decision in each period, is required to capture intertenrporal distortions. The model is extended later to the dynamic setting, along lines of the model of Ballard, et al. (1985). 13 characterized as constant returns to scale (CRTS).l4 Third, trade is based on the Armington assumption: Commodities are distinguished by their place or country of origin. ‘5 The assumption of national product differentiation is particularly convenient, because it allows us to use a very simple formulation to incorporate crosshauling (i.e., the simultaneous export and import of goods in the same commodity category), which is an important empirical feature of international trade. However, it should be noted that the Armington assumption has weaknesses. Brown (1987) criticizes this approach to product differentiation. She suggests that strong terms-of-trade effects can arise from the monopoly power implicit in national product differentiation. Therefore, she suggests that the Armington-type model may be fundamentally flawed for commercial policy analysis. An alternative approach is firm-level product differentiation, in which products are differentiated by firm, rather than by country of origin.16 (F inn-level product differentiation implies imperfect competition. See footnote 14.) However, the core model differs from the standard GTAP or GTAPinGAMS model in some important ways. The model is modified in the following ways: '4 The assumptions of perfect competition and CRTS have been criticized on grounds that they tend to underestimate the welfare gains of trade liberalization. Recent work in international trade has focused on imperfect competition and scale economies. Imperfect competition and scale economies are important subjects for my future work. '5 The products are nationally differentiated; for example, Japanese cars that are produced in Japan are distinct from American cars. Refer to Armington (1969). Most empirical evidences support national product differentiation: Jomini, Zeitsch, McDougall, Welsh, Brown, Hambley, and Kelly ( 1991) review the literature on estimation of the elasticities of substitution between domestic and imported goods, and conclude that those elasticities are low for almost all products. Reinert and Roland-Holst (1992) also estimate Armington elasticities ranging a low of 0. l4 and a high of 3.49, which implies that commodities are far from perfect substitutes. '6 This approach is based on the work of Spence (1976) and Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). Brown and Stern (1989) demonstrate that if the appropriate formulation is one of oligopoly with firm-level product differentiation, the approach of national product differentiation will provide a poor approximation of the welfare changes. 14 (1) Final demand in the standard GTAP is represented by the constant-difference- elasticity demand system. In the GTAPinGAMS model, final demand is of the Cobb- Douglas functional form. However, the utility function of the nested constant elasticity of substitution (CBS) form is incorporated in the core model here. The elasticity of substitution is allowed to vary between different groups of goods: the elasticity of substitution is large for close substitutes, and small otherwise. As shown in Shoven and Whalley (1992), the specific form chosen typically depends upon how elasticities are to be used in the model. The demands derived from the Cobb-Douglas utility function have the restrictions of unitary income and uncompensated own-price elasticities, and zero uncompensated cross-price elasticities. These restrictions are typically implausible, given empirical estimates of elasticities applicable to any particular model. However, these can be relaxed by using a more general functional form, such as the CES form. (2) The model incorporates a labor/leisure choice, by having leisure as an argument of the utility function. Among many simulation studies, Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987), Ballard, Fullerton, Shoven, and Whalley (1985), Fullerton and Rogers (1993), and Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1998) have adopted this approach. It is not possible to capture fully the distortionary effects of income taxes in a model with exogenous labor supply (such as the standard GTAP model or the GTAPinGAMS model). Since the model incorporates an endogenous labor-supply decision, the results reflect the fact that the income tax is distortionary. In addition, consumption taxes have an effect on the real wage rate, even if the net-of-tax nominal wage rate is unaffected. The model also captures the fact that this effect on the real wage rate will lead to changes in labor supply. 15 (3) The model incorporates a new method for calibrating the international capital flows. In our model, investors hold internationally diversified portfolios.l7 Consumers choose the portfolio shares of domestic and foreign assets, which are assumed to be imperfect substitutes in portfolios. As a result of changes in the relative rates of return, consumers are induced to alter the fractions of their financial wealth held in assets from different countries. (4) Various ad-valorem taxes are incorporated in the model, as in the GTAPinGAMS model; these include output taxes, taxes levied on intermediate inputs, export taxes, import tariff, and taxes levied on private demand. ‘8 Since there are no data for factor taxes in either the GTAP or the GTAPinGAMS database, the data for capital taxes and labor taxes, which are calculated on the basis of some statistics, are newly incorporated in the dataset.19 The corporate income taxes and the property taxes are treated as taxes on capital use by industry. The payroll taxes are treated as taxes on labor use by industry. The commodity taxes and the selective excise taxes are treated as consumer taxes on goods purchased. 17 The standard GTAP model assumes that international capital flows are allocated in response to changes in regional rates of return. The GTAPinGAMS model assumes exogenous international capital flows: it ignores the significant phenomenon of the expansion of international capital flows, so that it does not account for the spillover effects of the tax policy initiated by a country. '8 Since the GTAP database has no direct data for taxation, each tax rate is imputed, in the GTAPinGAMS database, using the corresponding values that are measured at both the tax-free price and the tax-inclusive price. '9 I deal with the method of calculating factor-tax rates, in Chapter 5. 16 Figure 3-1. The Structure of the Production D,-’ X ir I” level: i if Leontief technology over composite A intermediate inputs and value added 2"dlevel: 101', 11);, 10'.- CES function over capital and labor inputs 0', 3rd level: CES aggregation of domestic er' Kir and imported intermediate inputs CES aggregation of home-located capital owned by home resident and by foreigners 4'” level: ID 'I ID j; K," K 5’ CES aggregation of different imported intermediate inputs 0'17 SI' 3" SI“ 101.14%} ....... 1ng l7 3.2. Structure of the Static Model 3.2.1. Production Sector A “tree”, as shown in figure 3-1, represents the structure of the production side of the model. There are two types of produced commodities, domestic outputs and exports, which are assumed to be prefect substitutes. The assumption of perfect substitution is based on the fact that the goods produced for domestic consumption are nearly the same as those produced for exports: Toyota cars consumed in Japan are nearly the same as those consumed in the United States. Thus, the production activity levels, Qir , are represented as just the sums of domestic outputs and exports: Q{ = D{ +X,-’, (3.1) where the Dir are domestic outputs for good iproduced in region r, and the X ,-r are exports for good iproduced in region r. Composite intermediate inputs and value added are combined by a fixed- coefficient technology to generate these outputs, Qir : Q{ = miniIDfi,ID§,-, ....... ,ID;,,VA{(L;,K{)}, (3.2) where the ID}- are the intermediate demands for good j used in producing good i in region r, the VAl-r are the value-added functions, the L:- are the labor inputs used in the 18 production of good i in region r, and the K i" are the capital inputs used in the production of good i in region r. The primary factors, labor and capital, are combined according to a value-added function. Labor inputs are assumed to be mobile between production sectors, but not internationally. Capital inputs are assumed to be mobile across sectors and regions. For each sector in each region, a CBS fimction is employed to describe the functional relationship between the two primary factors: 0: i—l Ui—l O'i—l VA , VA . VAl(L.’-.Kl)=wi a.-' Li“ +[1—ar )xr “1 , (3.3) q VA where the w,- are scale parameters, the a: are share parameters, and the 0',- are the elasticities of substitution between labor and capital in sector i. Cross-ownership of capital is allowed in the model: both home residents and foreigners may own domestic capital. Therefore, producers make decisions about choosing capital owned by home residents and capital owned by foreigners. In the analysis, home-located capital owned by home residents and home-located capital owned by foreigners are assumed to be perfect substitutes, which means that producers are indifferent regarding whether their capital is owned by domestic residents or by foreigners. With infinite elasticities of substitution, the capital inputs are just the sums of capital owned by home residents and capital owned by foreigners: 19 Ktr(Krrr’Kisr)=Ktrr+Kiv’ (3'4) where the K i' r are home-located capital owned by home resident and used in sector i, and the K ,5 r are home-located capital owned by foreigners and used in sector i. The cost fimctions are represented as: C,-r(L;-',K,-r)= wa +rKl-r, (3.5) where the w are wage rates and the r are rental rates in region r. Minimizing the cost function (3.5) subject to a given technology (3.3), and manipulating some equations, gives us the unit cost functions, of (w, r): VA 0" VA 0" l-Ur cir(w,r)=i{[air ] wl—a’ +[1—air ) rl—a‘} , (3.6) 01 l l ‘l—Ui ‘ 1-0', VA r \ r L? (w,r)=Q_li airVA +[l—afVAJ a, r f (3.7) . VA W' (l—air )w _ J j 20 and '- rVA “1‘01 l—O’i l—ai W l . (3.8) r r K{(w,r)=—'i(1-a{ +a, i 61,- f VA ) VA Under the Armington assumption, which treats products in different regions as qualitatively different across countries, intermediate input demands, ID 1',- , are represented by a CBS aggregation of domestic and imported intermediate inputs. Off 0' ...... 1 1 ,- r ID ,7- yr r ID 5rd}: 01—1 ID-- =5}, a-- [DJ-,- a,-.- + 1—a-,- IDj. 0;.- , (3.9) J1 J1 J [D where the 51-,- are scale parameters, the 01;, are share parameters, the ID},r are domestically supplied intermediate input demands for good j used in producing good i in region r, the ID if are imported (from all foreign regions 3) intermediate input demands .. are the elasticities of for good j used in producing good i in region r, and the 0'], substitution between domestic and imported intermediate inputs. The intermediate input demand functions, ID},r and ID"? have the same form as J“ the factor-demand functions, (3.7) and (3.8): 20 See section 1 in the appendix for details. 21 ji T1_Uji l—O'j,’ ID D'-- ID ID) a'-- q‘-,- 10;; = 6" la},- +[1—a5, J 1' ID] i (3.10) .. r r 1' (l-aji )jS L L _ and ' ID ‘H’fii r—aj, r 1‘61}: qji v fl rm rm IDji — i l—aji +aji i , (3.11) 511' r ID 3 aji qji k h d J where the q ;,- are the producer prices of the domestically produced intermediate inputs, and the qj-i are the after-tariff producer prices of the foreign inputs. Sf Imported intermediate input demands, ID j,- , are also represented by a CES aggregation of the imported intermediate inputs from different regions: 5 aji ID if] Girl sr _ s Sic" 5.. [Dji _;ji Zafl ([Dji J 0’}, , 5k (3.12) 22 where the [Di-fr are imported (from region sk) intermediate input demands for good j used in producing good i in region r, and the oj-l- are the elasticities of substitution among imported intermediate inputs from different regions. As in the case of intermediate input demands, imported intermediate input demands, IDjfr , are represented by the formula: 0'}, [D s ——s [Djfr = {/1 J; 216,}. ) (qu) , (3.13) .. k jl q .. 5k 11 where the qj-f are the after-tariff produce prices of foreign country s k . 3.2.2. Demand Sector A representative agent determines final demand in each region. Figure 3-2 shows the structure of the decision-making process of the representative agent as a “tree”. I introduce the asset-holding function, to allow the consumer’s internationally diversified portfolio. On the first level, the consumer chooses the shares of domestic and foreign assets, which are assumed to be imperfect substitutes in financial wealth.21 The consumer’s asset holdings in region r, A’ , are represented by a CBS function: 2' The assumption that domestic and foreign assets are imperfect substitutes in the consumer’s portfolio is consistent with observed home-country preference; home-counny assets typically make up the bulk of portfolios, even when rates of return on foreign assets are comparable or higher. See Thalrnann, Goulder, and DeLorme ( 1996). French and Poterba (1991) empirically examine the international asset-ownership patterns, and find that most investors hold nearly all of their wealth in domestic assets. 23 Figure 3-2. The Structure of Utility 1" level. """""" g, CES aggregation of income from domestic capital 5 A and income from foreign capital ' 2’” level: H r _____________________________ CES aggregation of aggregate consumption and leisure //\>\od 3’“ level: Cr 2' CES aggregation of consumption demands among difi’erent sectors 0'“. h . 4’ level. C,” c; of CES aggregation of domestic and imported commodities 03m 5"I level: C i” C ,3 r CES aggregation of difi’erent imported commodities 0mm CW 032' cr‘k’ l l l A A at: -1 A . or: -1 0,5 -l Ar(rK"',r*KrS)= ar (rKrr 0;; +[l—ar )(r Krsi 0;}. , A . . where the or are share parameters, the of; are the elasticities of substrtutron between domestic and foreign capital assets, the rK " are income from domestic assets (home- located capital invested by home resident) in region r, and the r*K '3 are income from foreign assets (foreign-located capital invested by home resident) in region r.22 The consumer maximizes the asset-holding function, Ar , subject to the constraints, K = K ” + K rs , where K is fixed. The assumption of fixed number of capital invested by domestic residents is consistent with Harberger-type assumptions.23 These asset-holding functions can be represented by 2’ , which is a monotonic transformation of Ar : 22 In the model, the rK 's , not the K 'S themselves, are used as the arguments of the function, in a sense that the consumer cares about flows of income he gets from capital, not the capital itself. The r‘K rs are also the result of a CBS aggregation. 23 In the standard Harberger model of a closed economy, the total capital stock is fixed, but capital is mobile across sectors. It is as though owners of capital have a certain number of machines and rent them out to whichever sector offers the highest after-tax return. In that spirit, I assume that U.S. citizens own a fixed number of machines: K = K n + K rs , and have some allocation between K rr and K rs in the base case. When a policy change changes the after-tax returns on domestic and foreign investments, they may want to reallocate. Literally, this means that if the after-tax return goes up domestically, they will take some of the machines they were renting to frrm in Europe and bring them back to the U.S. to rent them to firms here. This seems a little unrealistic, but it is consistent with Harberger-type assumptions. 25 (3.15) Differentiating Z r with respect to the choice variable K '7 yields the first-order condition: Xi 04—1 i=0. (3.16) Totally differentiating with respect to (r / r') and K " , and manipulating it, I get the elasticity of demand for domestic capital with respect to the ratio of domestic and foreign rental rates, 77KB: 26 -1 A (r) ar Krr 4(CJGn D+0rs:r1 6K” * r K 771(1)E ” = 2 , (3.17) a[—-] K BF—D * r where A W A UrSA-l 04—1 _ 0;; 1 .r (1.) (Kw .4 .1...“ (Mn .4 ., r 04—1 —1 _1‘ A — - Dakar [ t 0,, Krrafs -(1—ar )(K—K” 0,1), r L J r 04—1 W A A —-l A _ —l and F-=- -0.67 c Elasticity Zero 0.15 0.74 :5 :0._59_ d U U Capital-F low :Efjects 1.23 8 Q1 b 999‘!” the case with holding constant trade parameters the case with holding constant trade parameters, and terms-of-trade effects at zero the case with holding constant asset parameters the case with holding constant asset parameters, and capital-flow effects at zero The capital-flow effects can be isolated from comparing the case with central and zero asset-substitution elasticities, holding constant trade parameters and also terms-of- trade effects at zero. In this simulation, the positive capital-flow effects are estimated as 1.3 percent of GDP. Similarly, the negative terms—of-trade effects, which lead to welfare losses of 0.6 percent of GDP, are estimated from comparing the case with central and big trade elasticities substitution, holding constant asset parameters and also capital-flow effects at zero. Lastly, Harberger effects, which amount to 0.7 percent of GDP, are estimated directly from the simulation with zero asset-substitution elasticity and big trade elasticity of substitution. Table 6-7 summarizes the results for other regions, as well as the United States. As shown in Table 6-7, the numbers representing the overall effects are not necessarily 81 equalized to the numbers, which are the sums of three effects. This is because some intersections among three effects are expected.59 The results show that the capital-flow effects are relatively dominant everywhere. For the U.S., the positive effects (the capital- flow effects and Harberger effects) dominate negative terms-of-trade effects. For other regions, the bigger negative capital-flow effects, which are associated with welfare changes of -0.9 percent of GDP, dominate the smaller positive terms-of-trade effects, which are associated with welfare gains of 0.3~0.4 percent of GDP. Table 6-7. Decomposing the Static EVs (Unit: % of GDP) U.S. E. U. Japan ROW A. Terms-of-Trade Eflects -0.59 0.39 0.29 0.36 B. Capital-Flow Efl'ects 1.31 -0.87 -0.94 -0.91 C. Harberger Eflects 0.74 Overall Effects 1 .38 -0.42 -0.61 -0.51 ’9 I find some intersections between the terms-of-trade effects and the capital-flow effects, in which the terms-of—trade effects are partly controlled by the asset-substitution elasticity. As domestic assets and foreign assets become closer substitutes, the terms-of-trade loss in the U.S. also becomes larger: The more sensitive investors are, the greater will be the increase in the quantity of capital supplied to the United States. As a result, a higher asset-substitution elasticity is associated with a larger decrease in the gross-of- tax price of U.S. capital. Consequently, a higher asset-substitution elasticity will be associated with a larger decrease in the price of U.S. exports, so that the deterioration of the terms of trade will be more severe. 82 6.2. Sensitivity Analyses In this section, I conduct sensitivity analyses for the key parameters: (1) trade elasticities of substitution, (2) asset-substitution elasticities, and (3) labor-supply elasticities. 6.2.1. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Armington Elasticities I start with a sensitivity analysis for the Armington trade elasticities of substitution, in which four possible cases are considered. These are: (a) changes in Udm (usa), (b) changes in O'dm (others) , (0) changes in 0mm (usa), and (d) changes in 0",", (others). The results are shown in Table 6-8 through 6-11, and briefly summarized in Table 6-12. (a) As the O'dm (usa) become larger, the terms-of-trade eflects become smaller."0 In other words, as imports become closer substitutes with domestically produced goods in the U.S., the terms-of-trade loss in the U.S. becomes smaller. The more sensitive domestic consumers are, the greater is the shift into domestically produced goods, and hence the greater will be the decreases in import prices. As the ad»: (usa) increases by 50 percent and 100 percent, the U.S. terms-of-trade loss becomes smaller by 33.2 and 52.3 percent (relative to the revised case with central-case parameters), and this leads to 6° This differs from the result in Brown (1987). She evaluates how national product differentiation relates to the terrns-of-trade effects of a tariff, and shows that the terms-of-trade effects would increase in magnitude, as the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported goods becomes larger. However, we find that the terms-of-trade effects are smaller when the elasticity of substitution is larger. This difference comes from the fact that imposing a tariff drives the export price up, whereas eliminating capital-income taxation drives it down. Imposing a tariff leads to an increase in export prices and a decrease in import prices, and thus generates terms-of-trade gains. When the elasticity of substitution is larger, the import prices fall farther, so that the terms-of-trade gains are increased. 83 an increase in the U.S. welfare gain by 8.0 and 14.5 percent (relative to the revised case with central-case parameters), respectively. Table 6-8. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Imported Goods 1’I o;m(usa) -50% ml” 25% 50% 100% (1.33) (2_._6_5) ° (3.31) (3.98) (5.30) (1) -233 (1) _-_1_.51 (1) -1.21 (1) -1.01 (1) -072 U.S. (2) 0.94 (2) 143 (2) 1.20 (2) 1.25 (2) 1.36 (3) 1.17 (3) L3 (3) 1.45 (3) 1.49 (3) 1.58 (1) 0.14 (1) w (1) 0.10 (1) 0.09 (1) 0.06 EU. (2) -051 (2) ._052 (2) -0.52 (2) -053 (2) -053 (3) -0.41 (3) -0_.4; (3) -042 (3) 0.43 (3) -043 (1) 0.33 (1) 023 (1) 0.19 (1) 0.16 (1) 0.14 Japan (2) -074 (2) M (2) -O.78 (2) -0.80 (2) -0.81 (3) -0.55 (3) M (3) -0.63 (3) -0.64 (3) -0.66 (1) 0.50 (1) 0._44 (1) 0.40 (1) 0.36 (1) 0.28 ROW (2) -047 (2) -_0_.6_6 (2) -053 (2) -052 (2) -050 (3) -054 (3) 0.51 (3) -0.47 (3) -045 (3) -040 a. (1) = % changes in terms of trade (2) = % changes in consumption level (3) = equivalent variation (as % of GDP) b. The central values of 02m are 2.43 for agriculture, 2.60 for primary materials, 3.40 for durable manufactures, 2.75 for non-durable manufactures, and 2.05 for services. c. The figures in the parentheses (of the column heading) are represented as the weighted average of 03m . 84 Table 6-9. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Imported Good H ’ 03m (teu) = 03m (ipn) = 02m (row) -50% mil” 25% 50% 100% (1.33) (2_._6_5_) ° (3.31 ) (3.98) (5.30) (1) -1.64 (1) 1.5_1 (1) -1.44 (1) -1.41 (1) -135 U.S. (2) 1.11 (2) up (2) 1.15 (2) 1.16 (2) 1.17 (3) 1.33 (3) 1_.33 (3) 1.40 (3) 1.41 (3) 1.43 (1) 0.10 (1) 012 (1) 0.13 (1) 0.13 (1) 0.14 EU. (2) -053 (2) 052 (2) -052 (2) -051 (2) -051 ’ (3) -044 (3) M (3) .042 (3) .041 (3) .041 (1) 0.23 (1) M (1) 0.23 (1) 0.23 (1) 0.23 Japan (2) -0.76 (2) ._076 (2) -0.76 (2) -0.76 (2) -0.76 (3) -0.61 (3) i)._6_1. (3) -0.61 (3) -O.61 (3) -0.61 (1) 0.47 (1) 0._44_ (1) 0.40 (1) 0.38 (1) 0.36 ROW (2) -0.65 (2) M0 (2) -0.67 (2) -0.67 (2) -0.68 (3) -0.51 (3) fl (3) -051 (3) .052 (3) -0.52 a. (1) = % changes in terms of trade (2) = % changes in consumption level (3) = equivalent variation (as % of GDP) b. The central values of of)", are 2.43 for agriculture, 2.60 for primary materials, 3.40 for durable manufactures, 2.75 for non-durable manufactures, and 2.05 for services. c. The figures in the parentheses (of the column heading) are represented as the weighted average of 02m. (b) As the cam (other) become larger, the terms-of-trade eflects become smaller. In other words, as the domestically produced goods in the foreign regions become closer substitutes with imports (i.e., with exports from the U.S.), the U.S. terms-of-trade loss 85 becomes smaller. After the change of the US tax policy, foreign consumers will consume more imports and fewer of their domestically produced goods, due to relative decline in the price of imports. The more sensitive foreign consumers are, the greater is the shift out of their domestically produced goods and into imported goods. This leads to decreases in U.S. import prices, and increases in US export prices, when compared with a situation in which the elasticities are smaller. Both the reduction of U.S. import prices and the rise in U.S. export prices will reduce the U.S. terms-of-trade loss. As the adm (others) increases by 50 percent and 100 percent, the U.S. terms-of-trade loss becomes smaller by 6.9 and 10.4 percent, and this leads to a small increase in the U.S. welfare gains. Figure 6-1. Terms-of-Trade Effects from Elimination of U.S. Capital Taxes, As a Function of the Elasticity of Substitution Between Domestic and Imported Goods (16 0A. (12 432 -OA -06 -08 -1 -12 -1A -16 cenUal 50% 100% 150% 200% 250% 300% 350% Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Imported Goods % Change of TOT 86 Based on (a) and (b), we can say that the terms-of-trade effects become smaller when the ad”, (all) become larger. Figure 6-1 shows that higher elasticities tend to produce weaker terms-of—trade effects. As the ad»: (all) are increased by near 350 percent, the terms—of-trade effects for the United States disappear. (c) As the 0mm (usa) become larger, there are no substantial changes in the terms-of-trade effects. The magnitudes of the elasticity of substitution among different imports in the U.S. don’t have a significant effect on U.S. import and export prices. This is to be expected. The terms-of-trade effects for the U.S. depend on the ease with which consumers can substitute between U.S. goods and goods from other regions, not on the ease with which U.S. consumers can substitute between goods from Germany and goods from Japan. Therefore, the U.S. welfare gains don’t change fi'om 1.4 percent, even if aim is increased. ((1) As the 0mm (others) become larger, the terms-of—trade effects become smaller. In the model, the elasticity of substitution among different imported goods in other regions, 0mm (others), has the same role as the elasticity of substitution between domestic and imported goods in the U.S., ad", (usa). As the 0",", (others) increases by 50 percent and 100 percent, the U.S. terms-of-trade loss become smaller by 26.6 and 45.1 percent, and this leads to an increase in the U.S. welfare gain by 6.4 and 11.8 percent, respectively. 87 Table 6-10. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution among Different Imported Goods I ’ 0.an (usa) -50% ge_ntr_alb 25% 50% 100% (2.66) (5_.3_0) ° (6.62) (7. 96) (10.60) (1) -152 (1) -1_.51_ (1) -1.51 (1) -151 (1) -150 U.S. (2) 1.13 (2) 1._1_3 (2) 1.13 (2) 1.13 (2) 1.13 (3) 1.38 (3) L3_8 (3) 1.38 (3) 1.38 (3) 1.38 (1) 0.11 (1) 0._12_ (1) 0.12 (1) 0.12 (1) 0.13 EU. (2) -052 (2) 0.52 (2) -052 (2) -0.51 (2) -0.51 (3) -0.42 (3) 3M2. (3) -042 (3) -042 (3) -0.42 (1) 0.23 (1) 9; (1) 0.23 (1) 0.23 (1) 0.24 Japan (2) -O.76 (2) -()_.76_ (2) -0.76 (2) -0.76 (2) -0.76 (3) -0.61 (3) M (3) -0.61 (3) -0.61 (3) -0.61 (1) 0.45 (1) 0L4 (1) 0.43 (1) 0.42 (1) 0.42 ROW (2) —0.66 (2) -_0._6_6 (2) -0.67 (2) -0.67 (2) -0.67 (3) -051 (3) -0_.51_ (3) -0.51 (3) -052 (3) -052 a. (1) = % changes in terms of trade (2) = % changes in consumption level (3) = equivalent variation (as % of GDP) b. The central values of of”, are 4.86 for agriculture, 5.20 for primary materials, 6.80 for durable manufactures, 5.50 for non-durable manufactures, and 4.10 for services. c. The figures in the parentheses (of the column heading) are represented as the weighted average of aim . 88 Table 6-11. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Elasticities of Substitution among Different Imported Goods H " ofnm (teu) = aim" (jpn) = aim (row) -50% m“ 25% 50% 100% (2.66) (5.30) c (6. 62) (7. 96) (10.60) (1) -2.44 (l) _-_1_._5_1 (l) -1.27 (1) -1.11 (1) -0.83 U.S. (2) 0.95 (2) 1g (2) 1.18 (2) 1.23 (2) 1.34 (3) 1.21 (3) LE (3) 1.43 (3) 1.47 (3) 1.54 (1) 0.14 (1) 0._12_ (1) 0.10 (1) 0.09 (1) 0.09 EU. (2) -0.50 (2) £5; (2) -0.53 (2) -0.53 (2) -0.54 (3) -0.45 (3) flA_2 (3) -0.42 (3) -0.43 (3) -0.43 (1) 0.28 (1) L2; (1) 0.20 (1) 0.17 (1) 0.15 Japan (2) -0.74 (2) M (2) -0.77 (2) -0.77 (2) -0.78 (3) -0.60 (3) M (3) -0.61 (3) -0.62 (3) -0.62 (1) 0.49 (1) 0_.4_4 (1) 0.40 (1) 0.38 (1) 0.36 ROW (2) -0.63 (2) £416 (2) -0.70 (2) -0.72 (2) -0.74 (3) -0.48 (3) M (3) -0.54 (3) -0.55 (3) -0.58 a. (1) = % changes in terms of trade (2) = % changes in consumption level (3) = equivalent variation (as % of GDP) b. The central values of Jim are 4.86 for agriculture, 5.20 for primary materials, 6.80 for durable manufactures, 5.50 for non-durable manufactures, and 4.10 for services. c. The figures in the parentheses (of the column heading) are represented as the weighted average of Jim. 89 Table 6-12. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Different Combinations of Trade Elasticities of Substitution " Elasticities of Substitution Changes 0.51m (usa) -50% m +50% +100% U.S. T.O.T. (% changes) -2.33 i5; -l.01 -0.72 (-54.17) 0.00 (33.19) (52.32) U.S. EV (as % ofGDP) 1.17 1A8 1.49 1.58 (-15.37) 0.00 (8.01) (14.49) 02m (tea): 0.2m (I'Pn)=0';m (row) -50% central +50% +100% U.S. TOT. (% changes) -1.64 i5; -1.41 —1.35 (-9.21) 0.00 (6.87) (10.37) U.S. EV (as % ofGDP) 1.33 138 1.41 1.43 (-3.91) 0.00 (2.34) (3.67) of" m (us a) -50% central +50% +100% U.S. T.O.T. (% changes) -l.52 ;l._51_ -l.51 -1.50 (-0.42) 0.00 (0.32) (0.59) U.S. EV(as % ofGDP) 1.38 1._38 1.38 1.38 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) (0.00) 0;m(teu)=01pm(ipn)=afnm (row) -50% central +50% +100% U.S. T.O.T. (% changes) -2.44 _-1._51_ -1.11 -0.83 (-61.43) 0.00 (26.56) (45.12) U.S. EV (as % ofGDP) 1.21 Q 1.47 1.54 (-12.03) 0.00 (6.39) (11.83) a. Numbers in parentheses represent percentage changes with respect to the values in the central case. 90 ' -’..‘.’ L‘Lw ”(3.-F 6.2.2. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Asset-Substitution Elasticities Secondly, I conduct a sensitivity analysis with respect to the asset-substitution elasticities. The elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign assets in portfolios, or”; , determines the ease of substitution between the two assets, and thus the degree of international capital mobility. When these elasticities of substitution are altered, there will be changes in the results of replacing the U.S. capital taxes. Table 6-13 reports the results. I take the central values of the asset-substitution elasticity as 2.0 for the U.S. and 1.5 for other regions. For the sensitivity analysis, the values of these elasticities of substitution are increased by up to 100 percent, to 4.0 and 3.0, to represent a greater degree of international capital mobility, and they are decreased by 100 percent, to zero, which represents no mobility of international capital. Under the U.S. tax-policy changes, as the asset-substitution elasticities become larger, there are more capital inflows into the United States. The more sensitive investors are, the more domestic capital is demanded, due to the higher after-tax returns in the United States. If 0;: is increased by 100 percent, the capital stock located in the U.S. will increase by 11.9 percent, relative to the base case. This compares with an increase of 8.5 percent when the central-case parameters are used. Consequently, the amount of capital outflow from the other regions will be substantially greater when the asset-substitution elasticity is larger than in the central case. (See Figure 6-2.) 91 Figure 6-2. Capital-F low Effects from Elimination of U.S. Capital Taxes, As a Function of the Elasticity of Substitution Between Domestic and Foreign Assets % Change of Capital Stock 400% -50% central 50% 100% Elasticities of Substitution between Domestic and Foreign Assets Table 6-13 also shows that higher asset-substitution elasticities are associated with larger increases in welfare gains in the United States. As of, is increased by 100%, the U.S. welfare gains increase by 43.5 percent, relative to the revised case with central- case parameters. However, the other regions experience more capital outflows, with higher asset-substitution elasticities. As of, is increased by 100%, the welfare losses for the other regions are increased by 33.3~40.5 percent. 92 Table 6-13. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Asset-Substitution Elasticities a Variables 0,4 -100% -5 0% c_en_tr_a_l b +5 0% +100% Capital Flows (% changes) U.S. 0.00 5.35 w 10.51 11.92 (-100.00) (-36.98) 0.00 (23.79) (40.40) E. U. 0.00 -1.46 -_1.84 -2.03 -2.15 (100.00) (20.65) 0.00 (-10.33) (-16.85) Japan 0.00 -2.00 M, -2.75 -2.93 (100.00) (21.26) 0.00 (-8.27) (-15.35) ROW 0.00 -1 .61 :24; -2.42 -2.60 (100.00) (24.41) 0.00 (-13.62) (-22.07) EV (as % of GDP) U.S. 0.15 1.03 fl 1.70 1.98 (-89.13) (-25.36) 0.00 (23.19) (43.48) E. U. 0.15 -O.14 i)._4_2_ -0.51 -0.59 (135.71) (66.67) 0.00 (-21.43) (-40.48) Japan 0.12 -0.29 M -0.73 -0.83 (119.67) (52.46) 0.00 (-19.67) (-36.07) ROW 0.17 -0.24 M -0.61 -0.68 (133.33) (52.94) 0.00 (-19.61) (-33.33) a. Numbers in parentheses represent percentage changes with respect to the values in the central case. b. The central values of 0;: are 2.0 for U.S., and 1.5 for other regions. 93 6.2.3. Sensitivity Analysis with Respect to the Labor-Supply Elasticities Next, I examine the implications of changing the uncompensated labor-supply elasticities, 77 L , and the total-income elasticity of labor supply, 7],. After the unilateral U.S. tax-policy changes, the demand for U.S. capital is expected to increase, due to the relatively higher after-tax returns in the United States. The higher demand for capital causes the wage rate to decrease. Also, the gross-of-tax prices of consumer goods in the U.S. are increased, because consumption taxes are used to replace the revenue lost as a result of the elimination of capital taxes. These price increases lead to decreases in the real wage rate. The decrease in labor supply will be greater when 77 L is greater. Labor supply can also be affected through the income effect, which is controlled by r] I . After the tax-policy changes, the consumer’s net capital income will be larger. Because of the increase in non-labor income, the consumer will enjoy more leisure, and thus will supply less labor. This effect will be greater when 771 is greater in absolute value. Thus, higher values of r] L and 771 (in absolute value) are associated with larger decreases in labor supply, through both the wage effect and the income effect. Consequently, a smaller welfare gain is expected when either of these labor elasticities is larger in absolute value. Figure 6-3 shows the effects of changes in the labor-supply elasticities on the welfare gains from the tax-policy change for the United States. The central values of 77 L and 771 are 0.15 and -0.1, respectively. As expected, the welfare gains for the U.S. are smaller when the labor-supply elasticities are larger in absolute value. However, the magnitude of this effect is relatively small. This indicates that other influences (such as 94 capital inflows, and the improvement in the efficiency of use of the capital stock) are more important than labor-supply effects, in determining the welfare gains.“ Figure 6-3. Welfare Gains for the U.S. fiom Unilateral Elimination of Capital Taxes, As a Function of Labor-Supply Elasticity -I- Total-Income Elasticity of Labor Supply = -0.01 +Total-Income Elasiticty of 1 .8 . Labor Supply = —0.05 -)(- Total-Income Elasticity of 1 6 ‘_ Labor Supply = -0.1 l (.4. — . i Liz! H. f Welfare Gains as % of GDP 0 0 .05 0 .1 0 .15 Uncompensated Labor-Supply Elasticities 6.3. Alternative Scenarios 6.3.1. U.S. Policy Changes of Different Sizes I investigate the optimal strategy for the United States, by simulating the analysis with alternative scenarios, in which U.S. government controls the size of the unilateral tax policy change. Figure 6-4 plots the U.S. equivalent variations, which correspond to policy changes of different sizes (from a 0% reduction to a 180% reduction in U.S. 6' Also, I note that I vary the labor-supply elasticities over a relatively small range, but this is because the econometric literature has made substantial progress toward identifying the labor-supply parameters. Most estimates of the elasticity of male labor supply fall within a fairly narrow range, and the range of estimates of female labor supply has been reduced in the last two decades. 95 capital taxes). As the size of the policy change increases, the EV increases at a diminishing rate. The EV reaches a maximum point at a 140% reduction in US capital taxes, but it falls sharply with greater reductions of U.S. capital taxes. If the U.S. were to reduce its capital taxes by 180%, it would actually suffer welfare losses. This is because the continued reduction in capital tax rates leads to a need for ever-greater increases in the consumption taxes that are used to replace the lost revenues. As the consumption-tax ? rates increase, their distortionary effects become dramatically larger. I conclude that an optimal strategy for the United States is to subsidize capital, if other countries don’t respond. 1 Figure 6-4. Optimal Strategy for the United States Welfare Gains as % of GDP or. 30% 60% 90% 120% 150% 180% Percent Reduction in U.S. Capital Taxes 6.3.2. Non-Zero Equalization of U.S. Capital Taxes Consider the policy in which U.S. capital-tax rates are equalized at a non-zero value. In this simulation, the rates are equalized at 32.2 percent, so that the revenues are 96 constant. Thus, U.S. consumption-tax rates are not increased in this case. Table 6—14 shows the U.S. domestic effects of non-zero equalization, and compares with the effects of zero equalization (which means complete elimination of capital taxes). Table 6—14. Domestic Effects of Non-Zero Equalization of U.S. Capital Taxes Non-Zero Equalization Zero Equalization Capital Flows by Sector (% changes) Agriculture -3.17 -1.26 Primary Materials -1 .34 4.32 Durable Manufactures 36.57 54.47 Non-durable Manufactures 1 1.28 18.76 Services 1.13 3.82 QM 4.17 8.49 EV (as % ofGDP) 1.07 1.38 With the policy of non-zero equalization of U.S. capital taxes, positive U.S. welfare gains are also expected. The equalized rates lead to a more efficient allocation of the U.S. capital stock. This policy change also has a positive effect on capital flows, but the size of the effect is smaller than in the case of complete elimination. The equalized U.S. capital-tax rate is still lower than the overall capital-tax rates in other regions. However, the equalized tax rates in some sectors, such as agriculture and primary materials, are even higher than the capital-tax rates in those sectors in other regions. The higher tax rates in those sectors lead the after-tax return on U.S.-located capital to move 97 downward in those sectors. This leads to capital outflows in those sectors (3.2 percent in agriculture, and 1.3 percent in primary materials), and thus drives in the direction of lessening the total amount of capital inflows in the United States. Consequently, comparing to the policy of complete elimination, the U.S. welfare gains are reduced (from 1.4 to 1.1 percent of GDP), since the capital inflows into the U.S. become smaller (from 8.5 to 4.2 percent). 6.3.3. Labor-Tax Replacement Consider the alternative scenario in which U.S. capital taxes are replaced by labor taxes, rather than by consumption taxes. As shown in Table 6-15, in the case of using labor taxes for equal revenue yield, the increase in the level of consumption and the welfare gains for the U.S. become larger. This can be mainly explained by the fact that the labor taxes are closer to uniform, while the consumption taxes are differentiated across SCCtOI‘S.62 Table 6-15. Domestic Effects of U.S. Labor-Tax Replacement Labor- Tax Consumption-T ax Replacement Replacement Consumption (% changes) 1.27 1.13 TOT (% changes) -0.96 -1.51 EV (as % ofGDP) 1.62 1.38 ’2 The sector-specific labor taxes are not differentiated across regions: The rates are around 13 percent in all sectors, except in services. See Chapter 5 for details. 98 In addition, the negative terms-of-trade effect becomes smaller, since the negative terms-of-trade effect is partly canceled by the increase in the labor taxes: If the sector- specific labor taxes are increased, there are increases in the gross-of—labor—tax prices of U.S. output. Thus, there is an increase in the prices of U.S. exports (the first-order effect). And there is also an increase in the prices of U.S. imports, due to higher demand for imports (the second-order effect). The dominant first-order effect leads to improVe the terms of trade in the United States. Table 6-16. Sensitivity Analyses with Different Combinations of Labor-Supply Elasticities and Goods Elasticity of Substitution E V with Labor- Tax E V with Consumption- Replacement Tax Replacement r] L (with a central value of (ICC) 0.0 2.35 1.87 0.15 a 1.62 1.38 0.30 1.30 1.22 ace (with a central value of T1L) 0.8 1.68 1.56 1.3 a 1.62 1.38 1.8 1.58 1.23 Combinations (0'ch 77 L ) (1.3, 0.15) 1.62 1.38 (0.8, 0.30) 1.34 1.23 (0.3, 0.60) 1.16 1.11 (0.1, 0.90) 1.02 1.01 a. central values 99 Table 6-16 shows how the U.S. welfare gains for both replacements are affected by the labor-supply elasticity and elasticity of substitution among goods. It is expected that the welfare gains with labor-tax replacement are directly controlled more by the labor-supply elasticity. If the uncompensated labor-supply elasticity becomes larger, we expect that the welfare gains for both replacements would be decreased. However, since .. the labor-supply elasticity has a more direct effect on the welfare gains with labor-tax replacement, changing the value of the labor-supply elasticity would have a greater effect on the welfare gains with labor-tax replacement, rather than on those with consumption- I. tax replacement. In the simulation, if the central value of the uncompensated labor-supply elasticity is doubled, the welfare gains with labor-tax replacement drop by 19.8 percent (from 1.6 percent of GDP to 1.3 percent of GDP), while those with consumption-tax replacement drop by 11.6 percent (from 1.4 percent of GDP to 1.2 percent of GDP). However, even though the absolute value of the change in EV is larger with labor-tax replacement, the ratio of EV with consumption-tax replacement to EV with labor-tax replacement doesn’t change much. Similarly, if the goods elasticity of substitution is larger, the decreases of the welfare gains with consumption-tax replacement are bigger than the decreases of those with labor-tax replacement. The last part of Table 6-16 shows that, if both a smaller goods elasticity of substitution and a larger labor-supply elasticity are assumed, the gaps between the welfare gains for both of these replacements become smaller. 100 6.3.4. Responses of Foreign Governments Finally, I consider the case of multilateral policy changes, in which other regions also eliminate their capital taxes. Figure 6-5 shows the comparison of the effects of unilateral and multilateral policy changes. The multilateral policy changes produce welfare gains for the entire world, whereas the unilateral policy changes produce a welfare gain only for the United States, which is the country undertaking the policy W changes. This is because the multilateral policy changes encourage more efficient use of capital everywhere. Figure 6-5. Welfare Effects - Unilateral vs. Multilateral 2 ,_ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ __ _. _.__._ ._..” 9d. 1.5 {D . . 80‘ 1 a I Unilateral Polrcy a\° I Multilateral Policy Q o 5 E ' 8 b o to _ «E g -0.5 US EU JPN ROW Region Table 6-17 shows the decomposition of the U.S. overall effects. The multilateral case produces less capital-flow effects, and less terms-of-trade effects, comparing to 101 unilateral case. Even though other regions also pursue same policy, the after-tax returns on U.S.-located capital are still relatively higher than the after-tax returns on foreign- located capital. This comes from the difference of characteristics of capital-tax structures for each region. The simultaneous eliminating of capital taxes also leads to smaller U.S. terms-of-trade losses. This is due to the fact that the terms-of-trade losses associated with a unilateral policy change are partially offset by terms-of-trade gains to trading -_ partners, when the policy change occur on a multilateral basis. For the United States, welfare losses associated with reduced capital inflows are almost offset by the extra welfare gains from the improvement of terms of trade. Thus, the multilateral case doesn’t lead to much change in U.S. welfare gains. Table 6-17. U.S. Static Welfare Changes of Multilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters (Unit: % of GDP) Trade Elasticity of Substitution Central Big T erms-of- Trade Effects Asset-Substitution Central 1.42 1.49 => -0.07 c Elasticity Zero 1.05 0.96 :> -0.09 d U U Capital-F low Effects 0.37 ’ Q._5_3 b a. the case with holding constant trade parameters b. the case with holding constant trade parameters, and terms-of-trade effects at zero 0. the case with holding constant asset parameters (1. the case with holding constant asset parameters, and capital-flow effects at zero 102 CHAPTER 7 DYNAMIC MODEL Thus far, I have analyzed the effect of U.S. tax reform with a static model, in which tax-policy evaluations are based on single-period equilibria. In this static framework, the distorting effects of capital taxes may be understated, since the effects on g saving decisions are not captured. The dynamic version of the model, in which consumers make a saving decision in each period, is required to capture intertemporal distortions. 7.1. Model and Calibration Issues The dynamic structure here involves multiple repetition of an essentially two- period maximization problem, which was used in the GEMTAP model. An alternative approach is the lifetime-utility—firnction approach, which involves maximization of a lifetime utility function, subject to a multiperiod budget constraint. This approach, which was used in Summers (1981) and Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1983), has become quite popular in recent years. Despite the popularity and some advantages of lifetime-utility- function approach, it has at least one serious problem.63 Under seemingly reasonable assumptions about the important parameters, such as the rate of time preference and the intertemporal substitution elasticity, the lifetime-utility-firnction approach can yield very high responses of savings to changes in tax rates. This problem does not arise in the GEMTAP model, which can be calibrated precisely to any desired savings elasticity. ’53 The problems of excessive intertemporal responsiveness were previously discussed in detail, in Chapter 2. Also, see Ballard (1987, 1990a) for further discussion. 103 The first equilibrium in every sequence is for the 1995 benchmark year. The equilibria in any sequence are connected to each other through capital accumulation. In other words, saving in the current period will augment the capital-service endowment available in the next period. The endowment of labor grows at a constant rate. In every sequence, the utility levels in region r, U r , are represented by a CBS fimction: 0115 _1 0h: -1 all: —1 F U’(H',Cf’)= 0’ H’ a... +(1—p’ )Cf’ a)... , (7.1) where the H r are current expenditure in region r, the C fr are future consumption in region r, and the Uhs are the elasticities of substitution between H r and C fr. That is, saving decisions are based on the maximization of a nested utility function, where the outer nest is defined over current expenditure (a composite of leisure and present- consumption goods) and the expected future-consumption stream made possible from savings. The consumer’s budget constraints are given by: PH’H’ +PS’s’ = wEr +71?” +7?" + TR' 5 Y1", (7.3) 104 where the PHr are the composite prices of leisure and present-consumption goods, the PS" Sr are the values of savings in region r, and the Y1" are region r’s expanded income, which includes the value of the consumer’s labor endowments, the value of the consumer’s capital income from domestic capital, the value of the consumer’s capital income from foreign capital, and transfer payments. As in the static framework, the allocation of capital between home and abroad is viewed as prior to the decision about current consumption and future consumption. In .1 this sense, the consumer’s capital income in (7.3) is treated as given, since it was derived from the maximization of Ar : A or: A 04-1 A 04-1 04-1 Ar(rK",r*Krs)= ar (rK")a,’; +(1—ar )(r'IKrsiar’: . (7.4) A where the 62’ are share parameters, the of, are the elasticities of substitution between domestic and foreign capital assets, the rK ” are income fi'om domestic assets (home- located capital invested by home resident) in region r, and the rTK ’5 are income from foreign assets (foreign-located capital invested by home resident) in region r. In this model, there is no financial intermediation between saving and investment. That is, a consumer buys investment goods directly with his savings. The model assumes that the consumer who buys S units of capital will realize a capital service flow of 75 105 per period,64 and each unit of capital services is expected to earn PK per period. This yield of saving is, in turn, sold for future consumption. Let Per be the price of consumption today. Under the assumption of static expectation, the consumer expects that firture consumption, C fr , will cost Pcr in each future year. Therefore, Pc'Cfr = PK’ySr. (7.5) Rearranging this, then I have: P rP r PS'S’ =( f) r; )cf’. (7.6) K This states that the value of saving equals the discounted present value of the expected future consumption that can be brought with that saving. Using (7.6), I can rewrite the budget constraints: P'P' PH’H’ +[-—5——C-]Cf’ = If. (7.7) \— 6‘ I assign to y the same value that I assign to r in the benchmark, 0.04. However, in GEMTAP, the Value of 7 is not same as r , because of the effect of personal taxes. 106 Constrained maximization of the utility functions F r yields the demand functions: F ahs Hr = —fl W (7 8) PHr ,- ,- 1_0hs . PKry r I and 1 ( \Uhs Cfr = 1_flF er 1—0' s ' PSrPcr F0713 rl—oh, F M PSrPcr h —P . fl PH +1-fl —— K K 7 J Ps'r (7.9) Now, I consider the calibration of the elasticity of substitution between current expenditure and future consumption. Differentiating the demand function for firture consumption in (7.9) with respect to PK yields: as = (1—pF)"’”K _s(1-pf)a”(a,,,-1)+s(a,,,-1) a 0' —1 6PK pKyWPSPCW ’“qj PK(PSPC) ’” ‘1' PK Pc PKI’ PK)’ , (7.10) 107 PSPc 1-0’ hs ] . Manipulating the demand PK)’ where ‘1’ =flFahs PHI—‘7’ls +(1—flF)ahs( function for future consumption and substituting into (7.10) gives us a simple expression for the saving elasticity: _as_§,_(_ = PKK _ PSs(a,,, —1) = + 0' -l . 7.11 p at), S ,1 Y1 ( h. ) ( ) Solving for O'hs gives: a K+S +1-— Y 6,, = s 1 . (7.12) 1__ Y1 The a h 5 parameters are calibrated to match with desired levels of the savings elasticity. Regarding the savings elasticity, the empirical literature is kind of a mix. Some articles give support for positive elasticities, but some also give support for negative elasticities, or for responses that are not distinguished from zero. In this study, I take the central value of the savings elasticity with respect to the return to capital (,0) to be 0.4, which was found by Boskin (1978), and then a sensitivity test with different values will be run. Boskin’s work has shifted the consensus toward the belief that the savings elasticity is positive. And, his estimates are generally statistically significant, and he suggests that they are economically significant, as well. 108 If constrained maximization of the utility function, U r , occurs repeatedly, then utility depends on a stream of consumption that extends infinitely into the future. When I move through the sequences, the capital stock grows because of saving. The growth rates of capital and labor are chosen so that the base case is indeed on a balanced grth path. 7.2. Simulation Results I analyze the dynamic effects of changes in U.S. tax policy on the global economy. Here again, I consider the complete elimination of U.S. capital taxes. The lost revenues are replaced with higher rates of consumption taxes. Under the dynamic framework, the future path of the economy can be analyzed explicitly. Table 7-1 through 7-3 plot the transitional dynamic paths of consumption, leisure, and utility in all regions. The vertical axis represents the deviations from the pre-tax-reform equilibrium, in percentage terms. The first 40 years of the sequence of equilibria are shown on the horizontal axis. Figure 7-1. Constnnption Path - All Regions Devrattons m % (of Pre- T ax-Reform Eq 'm) Period 109 . .l Aunt-L finals.” 1' (_ Deviations in % (of Pre- T ax—Reform Eq 'm) Deviation in % (of Pre- T ax-Reform Eq 'm) 1 o '01 Figure 7-2. Leisure Path - All Regions c.) '01 —4 m 'cnm'oroo o o'tn l 7‘ l 01 —L Period Figure 7-3. Utility Path - All Regions 110 8...... The U.S. consumption and utility paths are shown to be growing at a stronger pace, while the other regions have flatter paths of consumption and utility. This is because of higher capital accumulation, along with capital inflows to the United States. Now, I investigate the dynamic effects on the U.S. domestic economy in detail. To investigate the transitional effects, I also consider the case in which lost revenues are replaced with higher rates of labor taxes, and compare the results to the case with higher rates of consumption taxes. Table 7-1 shows the dynamic results of impact and long-run effects. Consider first the case in which capital taxes are replaced by higher consumption taxes. The impact effects show that the consumption level drops by 1.6 percent, and the utility level decreases by 0.6 percent, relative to the pre-tax-reform equilibrium. The level of consumption falls sharply, since the increase in output level is surpassed by the increase in the savings level. The decrease in the utility level is rather smaller, due to the increase of leisure. The decrease in the net wage rate leads to a substantial increase in leisure. In the long run, utility level increases by 4.0 percent, mostly due to higher increases in consumption level. In the second case, in which capital taxes are replaced by labor taxes, the impact effects show that the utility level decreases by 0.1 percent, relative to the pre-tax-reform equilibrium. This is due to small decreases in the consumption level, at the time of the changes in tax policy. The level of consumption does not move so much in the case of labor-tax replacement, while it falls sharply in the case of the replacement with consumption taxes, since an increase in the output level is almost canceled by an increase in the savings level. The increase in leisure is larger than that in the case of consumption- 111 tax replacement, since the increase in labor taxes directly leads to a increase in leisure. In the long run, consumption and utility level increase by 4.5 and 3.9 percent, respectively. Table 7-1. The Impact and Long-Run Effects of Replacing of U.S. Capital Taxes (Unit: % Changes 8’) Replacing by Consumption Tax Replacing by Labor Tax Impact Eflect Long-Run Effect Impact Eflect Long-Run Efl'ect Consumption -1 .62 5.60 -0.63 4.45 Leisure 2.97 0.70 3.12 1.20 Utility -0.55 4.00 -0.06 3.86 a. Figures are percentage changes relative to pre-tax-reform equilibrium. Figure 7-4. Consumption Path - U.S. or 1 01 D h T ff— ' 1 ‘ 1.0-CTR 3 +LTR l l Devratrons in % (of Pre— T ax-Reform Eq ’m) o ..L I p .. _ b .. - _ h— .. _ _ .. p- _ )— h .. ._ . .. .. j- p— p- )- )- .. b- hr )- b .. ._ L- )- h l I ‘ I N 1 Period 112 Figure 74 through 7-6 show the transitions of consumption, leisure, and utility level in the United States, after the policy shock occurs in the first year. In the case of the replacement with consumption taxes, the level of consumption is lower in the first year, by around -1.6 percent. However, consumption then rises at a faster rate, as a result of the greater amount of capital accumulation. The level of consumption approaches a new balanced-growth path asymptotically, and reaches a gain of 5.6 percent from the base ff“ case beyond year 40. In the case of replacement with labor taxes, consumption rises at a slower rate, and reaches a gain of 4.5 percent from the base case beyond year 40. The paths of leisure in both cases have similar shapes: the level of leisure is higher at first year, and then decreases as time goes on. With the labor tax replacement, labor decreases more, and thus leisure increases more. Figure 7-5. Leisure Path - U.S. 9° 01 w 2.4 N CI 1 .11 " +CTR um.“— +er N t (I! _J _A 01 i d D Devzatrons m % (of Pre- T ax-Reform Eq ’m) .0 U! i 1 5 9 13 17 21 25 29 33 37 41 Period 113 Figure 7-6. Utility Path - U.S. & O) Devratrons tn % ( of-Pre- T ax-Reform Eq 'm) d N O Period Figure 7-7. U.S. Consumption Path, As a Function of Savings Elasticity -0- savings elasticity=0.4 + savings elasticity=0.2 + savings elasticity=0.0 Devratrons in % (of Pre-T ax-Reform Eq 'm) Period 114 I also report the sensitivity analysis of the U.S. consumption path with respect to savings elasticity. As shown in Figure 7-7, for a larger savings elasticity, consumption drops farther at first, and then it recovers more quickly, and the level of consumption finally reaches at higher point at year 40, compared to the lower-elasticity case. Last, I calculate the dynamic welfare gains, using the present value of the stream of the equivalent variation over 40 years and more.65 Although the economy approaches 3‘ the new steady state closely by the end of 40 years, I use longer periods to ensure that the approach to the new steady state is very close.66 The approximation is involved in calculations of the termination term.67 Table 7-2 and 7-3 show the results of a unilateral nl-n-v—v 1‘; -u.-—A._-I _- policy change. The results show that a 100-year simulation provides a U.S. welfare gain of around $4.0 trillion, while a 200-year simulation provides around $4.1 trillion. These amount to about 2.2 percent of GDP stream, which are discounted over the simulation period (vs. 1.4 percent of GDP in static simulation). The welfare losses for the European Union, Japan, and the Rest of World are 0.4~0.7 percent of their GDP streams (vs. 0.4~0.6 percent of their GDP in static simulation). The welfare gains of a multilateral policy change are shown in Table 7-4 and 7-5. The results show that a 100-year simulation yields a U.S. welfare gain of around $3.3 65 For dynamic welfare evaluation, I use the H r function, not the U r function. If savings are included in the evaluation of utility in the current period, the “double counting” problem would happen, since savings are used to buy future consumption. 66 The dynamic procedure here does not guarantee that the change in welfare will be invariant with respect to the numbers of years between first and last equilibrium. In general, the longer is the numbers of years, the closer is the equivalent variation to the actual steady-state value. See Ballard, et al. (1985) for details. 67 Over 40 years in a revised-case calculation, the economy asymptotically approaches a new steady state. However, it will not actually reach the new steady state. As far as a policy is designed to increase saving, the economy will still be experiencing a small amount of capital deepening, even after many years. For calculating the termination term, I assume a slight decrease in saving from the amount that I actually calculated for the termination year. 115 trillion, while a ZOO-year simulation yields around $3.4 trillion. These amount to about 1.8 percent of GDP stream, which are discounted over the simulation period (vs. 1.4 percent of GDP in static simulation). Under a multilateral policy change, other regions also have welfare gains, which amount to about l.1~1.2 percent of their GDP streams (vs. 0.5~0.6 percent of their GDP in static simulation). Table 7-2. The Equivalent Variation I - Dynamic Simulation of Unilateral Case (Unit: Billions of 1995 Dollars) Simulation Period U.S. E. U. Japan ROW 40 2,735.38 -88l.81 -888.58 -1,165.95 60 3,475.34 -872.91 —887.14 -1,159.94 80 3,813.35 -868.85 -886.48 -1,156.75 100 3,967.75 -866.99 -886.18 -1,155.29 120 4,038.28 -866.15 -886.05 -1,154.62 140 4,070.50 -865.76 885.98 -l,154.32 160 4,085.22 -865.58 -885.96 -1,154.18 180 4,091.94 —865.50 -885.94 -1,154. 12 200 4,095.01 -865.46 -885.94 -1,154.09 116 Table 7-3. The Equivalent Variation II - Dynamic Simulation of Unilateral Case (Unit: % of GDP Stream) Simulation Period U.S. E. U. Japan ROW 40 1.84 -0.54 -0.84 -0.68 60 2.06 -0.47 -0.74 -0.60 80 2.15 -0.44 -0.70 -0.56 100 2.18 -0.43 -0.68 -0.55 120 2.19 -0.43 -0.68 -0.54 140 2.20 -0.43 -0.67 -0.54 160 2.21 -0.43 -O.67 -0.54 180 2.21 -0.42 -0.67 -0.54 200 2.21 -0.42 -0.67 -0.54 Table 7-4. The Equivalent Variation III - Dynamic Simulation of Multilateral Case (Unit: Billions of 1995 Dollars) Simulation Period U.S. E. U. Japan ROW 40 2,329.59 1,524.93 826.99 1,418.34 60 2,905.79 1,978.86 1,147.78 1,892.14 80 3,169.00 2,186.13 1,294.07 2,108.40 100 3,289.24 2,280.76 1,360.79 2,207.11 120 3,344.16 2,323.97 1,391.21 2,252.16 140 3,369.25 2,343.69 1,405.83 2,272.72 160 3,380.71 2,352.70 1,411.41 2,282.11 180 3,385.94 2,356.81 1,414.30 2,286.39 200 3,388.33 2,358.69 1,415.61 2,288.35 117 Table 7-5. The Equivalent Variation IV - Dynamic Simulation of Multilateral Case (Unit: % of GDP Stream) Simulation Period U.S. E. U. Japan ROW 40 1.57 0.93 0.78 0.83 60 1.72 1.11 0.95 0.97 80 1.78 1.11 1.03 1.03 100 1.81 1.14 1.05 1.05 120 1.82 1.15 1.06 1.06 140 1.82 1.15 1.07 1.06 160 1.83 1.15 1.07 1.07 180 1.83 1.15 1.07 1.07 200 1.83 1.16 1.07 1.07 Table 7-6. U.S. Dynamic Welfare Changes of Unilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters (Unit: % of GDP) Trade Elasticity of Substitution Central Big T erms-of- Trade Efi'ects Asset-Substitution Central 2.22 2.54 :> -0.32 c Elasticity Zero 1.01 1.24 :> fl d U U Capital-F low Effects 1.21 a fig b the case with holding constant trade parameters the case with holding constant trade parameters, and terms-of-trade effects at zero the case with holding constant asset parameters the case with holding constant asset parameters, and capital-flow effects at zero 9*? 9‘1” 118 Next, the overall U.S. welfare effects of a 200-year simulation are decomposed. I consider both a unilateral case and a multilateral case. The results are shown in Table 7-6 and 7-7. The capital-flow effects and the terms-of-trade effects can be isolated, through the same process used in the static case. The method of isolating Harberger effects is different. In the static case, the numbers being estimated directly from the simulation with zero asset-substitution elasticity and big trade elasticity of substitution simply F represent Harberger effects (0.74 in Table 6-6, and 0.96 in Table 6-17). However, in the l dynamic case, they can’t be interpreted as only Harberger effects (1.24 in Table 7-6, and r 1.58 in Table 7-7). Since they include the positive effects on saving decision, which are not captured in the static framework, they must be interpreted as the sum of Harberger effects and the intertemporal effects. As shown in Table 7-8, the intertemporal effects are estimated as 0.5~0.6 percent of GDP. Table 7-7. U.S. Dynamic Welfare Changes of Multilateral Case, As a Function of the Trade and the Asset Parameters (Unit: % of GDP) Trade Elasticity of Substitution Central Big Terms-of— Trade Effects Asset—Substitution Central 1.83 1.84 :> -0.01 c Elasticity Zero 1.49 1.58 :5 002 d U U Capital-F low Effects 0.34 a M b the case with holding constant trade parameters the case with holding constant trade parameters, and terms-of-trade effects at zero the case with holding constant asset parameters the case with holding constant asset parameters, and capital-flow effects at zero 999'?” 119 Table 7-8. Intertemporal Effects for the U.S. (Unit: % of QD_P_) Static Dynamic Intertemporal Effects Unilateral Ca_sg a E V 0.74 1 .24 :5 0.50 Multilateral Case 3 EV 0.96 1.58 :5 0.62 5""? a. the case with zero asset-substitution elasticity and big trade elasticity of substitution Table 7 -9. Welfare Effects for Whole World U.S E. U. Japan ROW W_orlg' Unilateral Case EV ($ billions) ’ 4,095.01 -865 .46 -885.94 -1,154.09 1,189.52 EV (% of World GDP Stream) 0.16 Multilateral Case EV ($ billions) 3,388.33 2,358.69 1,415.61 2,288.35 9,450.98 EV (% of World GDP Stream) 1.28 a. Units are in parentheses. So far, I focused on each region’s welfare gains or losses, rather than welfare effects for whole world. Now, I calculate the overall welfare gains in both unilateral and multilateral case, using a ZOO-year simulation. Table 7-9 shows that a unilateral policy change yields world welfare gains of around $1.2 trillion. These amount to about only 120 0.2 percent of world GDP stream, which are discounted over the simulation period. However, under a multilateral policy change, the world enjoys tremendous welfare gains of $9.5 trillion, which amount to about 1.3 percent of world GDP stream. The results show that a worldwide tax reform is superior over a unilateral tax reform, in a sense that a worldwide reform leads to larger world welfare gains. 121 CHAPTER 8 CONCLUSION This paper has described a global trade model in which international spillover effects can occur through changes in commodity flows and changes in capital flows. I use both static and dynamic computational general-equilibrium models that divide the world into four regions. The data are from Global Trade Analysis Project for 1995. My model incorporates a labor/leisure choice and international cross-ownership of assets. I report and interpret the results of simulations of changes in U.S. tax policy. In the static simulation, I find that unilateral elimination of U.S. capital taxes generates welfare gains for the United States. The tax-policy changes improve the allocation of the domestic capital stock, and they generate capital inflows, but they also generate negative effects on the terms of trade. The positive effects dominate the negative effects, so that U.S. welfare is improved. Conversely, foreign economies experience capital outflows, along with positive terms-of-trade effects. Since the positive terms-of-trade effects are dominated by the negative capital-flow effects, the foreign economies have welfare losses. However, when all regions remove their capital taxes, the entire world experiences welfare gains. As the trade elasticities of substitution become larger, the terms-of-trade effects become smaller. A larger asset-substitution elasticity causes larger capital-flow effects, and it also causes larger terms-of-trade effects. When labor supply is more elastic, the welfare gains are reduced. 122 Under the dynamic framework, the future path of the economy is analyzed explicitly. The consumption path for the United States is shown to be growing at relatively stronger pace, while the other regions have a flatter path of consumption, because of higher capital accumulation, along with capital inflows to the United States: The U.S. consumption is decreased in the first year when the policy shock occurs. However, the level of consumption then rises at a faster rate, and finally approaches a new balanced-growth path asymptotically. With a larger savings elasticity, consumption drops farther at first, and it recovers more quickly. The analysis of welfare gains for the United States indicates that unilateral elimination of U.S. capital taxes yields dynamic gains, whose present values are around $4.0~$4.1 trillion, while it yields an annual static welfare gain of around $98 billion in 1995 dollars. The dynamic gains are estimated as 2.2 percent of GDP stream, while the static gain is estimated as 1.4 percent of GDP. If all regions adopt the policy changes, the dynamic gains for the United States are 1.8 percent of GDP stream, compared with 1.4 percent of GDP in the static case. 123 Illa, L APPENDIX 1. Factor Demand Functions with CES A firm with CES technologi demands quantities 35,- of factor i when market prices are p,- and taxes are ti. Assuming an elasticity of substitution equal to 0', find the compensated demand for the ith factor when market prices and taxes are given by p j and tj 5'" The production function is CES, so it can be written: 1 y=r/J{axlp +0—61ka ,where p=OI—c;l The compensated demand functions for this production function can be then derived using standard Lagrangean techniques: Q L Q ..L Tilq L=P1(1+11)X1 +P2(1+’2)x2 +4 y-l/I an" +(1—alx20 If this is differentiated with respect to x1 and x2 , 124 o—l __ __ _1 _ p1(1+tl)=Ay/(;3_—l) axl" +(1—a)x20 0(00 )x10 (1) 1 9:1 0_-1 E 1 :1. p2(1+tz)=Aw(}E_—1) 66.10 +(1—a)x2" (1—a{0; )x20 (2) Dividing (1) by (2), and arranging for x2 , x2 {fill—”21.000231, (3) P2(1+’2) 0 Putting (3) into the cost ftmction, C=P1(1+’1)X1+P2(1+12)x2 =(,1(1,,1».{a001(1+n)1rAlgerian-(2)50 W a Therefore, compensated demand functions can be written: 125 C =ip1(1+t1)} “0(P1(1+’1))1-0 +(1—a)a(Pz(l+t2))l-a (4) and C _ l-a 0 x2 _ {P2(1+t2 )} aa(p1 (1+t1))1"’ +(1—a)a(p2 (1+t2 ))1’0 (5) For simplicity, let a“ (pl (1 + t1))1"a + (1 — a)” (p2 (1 + t2 ))1_‘7 s A , and putting (4) and (5) into the production function, mv‘ 9;] 3;] 0-1 y_,,a(__a_]a£ " ,(1_a(__1_1_]a£ " , ) P104411 A P204421 A L =l/ICA0‘1 Now, we can get the unit cost function: C C _1__ cE—z =I/I—1A1—0 (6) y L 126 1 fibres not-0 + (1 -a)"(pz(1 “Zr-“F Putting (6) into equations (4) and (5), we get associated demand functions: +18%) and y (1 - all/'6 a x, = _ (8) ll! P2 (1 + ’2) Next step is to calibrate functional parameters to a single benchmark equilibrium.68 From (3), we get the value of a: 1 171(13‘1-1181" _ 51(13‘5117711—‘0 1 1 _ _ - —1-p _ - ...1-p - — - — P1(1+t1)x1 +P2(1+12)x2 171(1+t1)3510 +P2(1+12)ff If we define 0 as the value share of x1 at the benchmark point: 6’ In most large-scale applied general-equilibrium models, we have many function parameters to specify with relatively few observations. The conventional approach is to calibrate functional parameters to a single benchmark equilibrium. See GAMS Development Corporation (1998). 127 '[u (VHF-‘3- 51044-031 §1(1+t—1)31+§2(1+52)52 6: then the relationship between 6 and a is presented: —p “*1 ail” + (1 — 61);; 9: And, we get the value of w from the production function: V] = fézi’lp +(1—a)5f2p}_% Using these calibrated parameters, the cost and demand functions can be expressed as the calibrated share from. In the calibrated form, the cost and demand functions explicitly incorporate benchmark demands, benchmark factor price, benchmark tax rate, the elasticity of substitution, benchmark cost, benchmark output, and benchmark value share. First, the production fimction in the calibrated share form is presented, using the value of 52' and (9: l p p _ y=5i 6E1] duet—2] p (9) x1 12 128 Qnfi Next, using the value of E and 0 , the unit cost function in the calibrated share form is presented: 1 c = EMMY—G + (1 — oiMJI-o I; (10) 510+?” 52(1+t.2) Lastly, the compensated demand fianction in the calibrated share form is presented: and Therefore, in general, the unit compensated demand function in the calibrated share form (37 = 5 =1) can be expressed: 1 —. -. a . . 1-0 E xizfi[£l-(-l+—tlk] ,where C= 26i(£_l_(_lit_12] (11) Pi(1+ti) 51'0“?) i 129 2. Compensated Demand Functions with CES A consumer with CES utility consumes quantities 1?,- when market prices are pi. Assuming an elasticity of substitution equal to 0', find the compensated demand for the ith good when market prices are given by p j- The utility function is CES, so it can be written: 1 U={mlp+(1—a)x§}; ,where [3:931 Constrained maximization of the utility function U yields the compensated demand functions: a a Y x1 = {_} 0' 1—0 0' 1—0' (1) pl 0: p1 + (1 — a) p2 and a l—a Y x2={ } 0' 1—0' a 1—0' (2) P2 (1 p1 +(1—a) [)2 For simplicity, let (zapll-U + (1 — or)"r p21—0 a A , and putting (1) and (2) into the utility function, we have the indirect utility function: 130 rm! fi‘ “—3. 0' ' 2:1 91‘ :1 0' a _ a 0' V=Ta[£) Z +(1—a(1—a-] Z > P1 A P2 A L J L = YAC"1 So, the expenditure function is expressed: ...L E = VAl“I 1 =V(a0p11'0 +(1_a)0p21-01-o (3) Next step is to calibrate functional parameters to a single benchmark equilibrium. We get the value of a: l _ __ _ _1— Plxla _ P1X] p ' 1 1 ‘ _ —l-p _ —l—p __ _; _ _; Plxl +p2x2 Pix] +p2x2 If we define 9 as the value share of x1 at the benchmark point: 131 P1x1 FIE] + 52372 then the relationship between 6 and a is presented: Cit-1p F ‘m " ._.— _ ail” + (1 —a)ff And, we get the value of (7 from the utility function: l mama—w Using these calibrated parameters, the demand functions can be expressed as the calibrated share from. First, the utility function in the calibrated share form is presented, using the value of (7(=1) and 6: 1 p p — U: 6(9) 4149(9) p (4) x1 x2 Next, using the value of E(= 1) and 19 , the unit expenditure function in the calibrated share form is presented: 132 1—0 1-0' 1; e: 19%?) +(1—0(€—2] (5) And, lastly, using the relationship between the expenditure and the indirect utility functions: the compensated demand function in the calibrated share form is presented: and Therefore, in general, the unit compensated demand function in the calibrated share form ((7 = E =1) can be expressed: 133 e_- 0' . 1—0' 1-0 x,- = 3V [—11] , where e: 2 6(35] and V = Pi i 3. Supply Functions with CET A firm with a CE T technology produces joint products (outputs) 1?,- when market prices are [7,- and output tax is ty. Assuming a constant elasticity of transformation equal to 77 , let ’s find the supply functions of the ith output when market prices and taxes are given by p 1- and ty. The production function is CET, so it can be written: L 1:1 L“ n+1 y=y1 axl" +(1—a)x2'7 Constrained maximization yields the supply fimctions (assuming same output taxes on two products): of" C p"7(1—z ) a"? 1+”441—01)"? “’7 1 y P1 P2 (1) XI: 134 and 1— W C x2 = (‘77 a) -—77 1+7; —77 1+7; (2) p2 (l-ty) a p1 +(1—a) p2 For simplicity, let of” p11“? + (1 — a)_'7 p?" a A , and putting (1) and (2) into the production function, ,L ’7_+.1 ’7_"1 0+1 -0 '1 _ --n '7 W1 ,7 :2 +1-: —“.,,“) % > P (1'0) P2(1'ty) “L l-ty Now, we can get the unit cost function: 1 _C C —1 fl c=;= _;_ =w A 6—9) a) WCA 0+1 ._1_ l—ty 135 .. ML «ILLIY Putting (3) into equations (1) and (2), we get associated supply functions: “’7 x1 = {l){ all/C } (4) V’ pl 1—ty and -n y (1 - QWC x, = ._ (5) [wllpzll -ty )} Next step is to calibrate functional parameters to a single benchmark equilibrium. We get the value of a: l — - r7 P1X] 1 l —— 77 — — 7) Plxl +P2x2 If we define 6 as the value share of x1 at the benchmark point: 1713‘] Eli] + 523-2 6: then the relationship between 6 and a is presented: 136 1.} n+1 17:1 air—1'7 + (1 ——a)fz'7 And, we get the value of 1/1 from the production fimction: .1 0+1 n+1 "+1 111:; 0551" +(1—a)5c’2'7 Using these calibrated parameters, the cost and demand functions can be expressed as the calibrated share form. First, the production function in the calibrated share form is presented, using the value of 5; and 6: 2:1 17:1 5 y=y 6(—’§‘— " +(1-49)(i‘.—2 ” (6) 11 J‘2 Next, using the value of E and 0 , the unit cost function in the calibrated share form is presented: 1+7; 1+1; 1? _ c=E 9(9) +04%?) ’7 (1 t’) (7) 137 Lastly, the supply function in the calibrated share form is presented: and Therefore, in general, the unit supply function in the calibrated share form (y = E =1) can be expressed: 01' x. z . (8) ~ ~ H 138 BIBLIOGRAPHY Altig, David, Alan J. Auerbach, Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Kent A. Smetters, and Jan Walliser (2001), “Simulating Fundamental Tax Reform in the United States.” American Economic Review 91: 574-595. Altshuler, Rosanne, Harry Grubert, and T. Scott Newlon (1998), “Has U.S. Investment Abroad Become More Sensitive to Tax Rates?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 6383 (January). Armington, Paul S. (1969), “A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production.” I.M.F. Staffs Papers 16 (March): 159-178. Auerbach, Alan J ., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff (1983), “National Savings, Economic Welfare, and the Structure of Taxation.” In Martin Feldstein (ed.), Behavior Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Auerbach, Alan J ., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff (1987), Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. Auerbach, Alan J ., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Kent Smetters, and Jan Walliser (1997), “Fundamental Tax Reform and Macroeconomics Performance.” In Joint Committee on Taxation Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, prepared and compiled by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. Washington, DC: USGPO (November). Ballard, Charles L. (1987), “Tax Policy and Consumer Foresight: A General Equilibrium Simulation Study.” Economic Inquiry 25: 267-284. Ballard, Charles L. (1990a), “On the Specification of Simulation Models for Evaluating Income and Consumption Taxes.” In Manfred Rose (ed.), Heidelberg Congress on Taxing Consumption. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. Ballard, Charles L. (1990b), “Marginal Welfare Cost Calculations: Differential Analysis vs. Balanced Budget Analysis.” Journal of Public Economics 41 (2): 263-276. Ballard, Charles L. (2000), “How Many Hours Are in a Simulated Day? The Effect of Time Endowment on the Results of Tax-Policy Simulation Models”. Working Paper, Michigan State University (June 28). Ballard, Charles L. (forthcoming, 2002), “International Aspects of Fundamental Tax Reform.” In Peter Mieszkowski and George R. Zodrow (eds.), United States Tax Reform in the 21 " Century. Cambridge, England, and New York: Cambridge University Press. 139 l.\-*“F Ballard, Charles L., Don Fullerton, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley (1985), A General Equilibrium Model for Tax Policy Evaluation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Boskin, Michael J. (1978), “Taxation, Saving, and the Rate of Interest.” Journal of Political Economy 86: 83-827. Boskin, Michael J ., and William G. Gale (1987), “New Results on the Effects of Tax Policy on the International Location of Investment.” In Martin Feldstein (ed.), The Eflects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. .3,“ Brown, Drusilla K. (1987), “Tariffs, the Terms of Trade and National Product Differentiation.” Journal of Policy Modeling 9: 503-526. Brown, Drusilla K., and Robert M. Stern (1989), “United States-Canada Bilateral Tariff Elimination: The Role of Product Differentiation and Market Structure.” In R.C. Feenstra (ed.), Trade Policies for International Competitiveness. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. g} Burtless, G. (1987), “The Work Response to a Guaranteed Income: A Survey of Experimental Evidence.” In A. H. Munnel(ed.), Lessons from the Income Maintenance Experiments. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 30. Carone, G. (1996), “Modeling the U.S. Demand for Imports through Cointegration and Error Correction.” Journal of Policy Modeling 18 (1): 1-48. Deyak, Timothy A., W. Charles Sawyer, and Richard L. Sprinkle ( 1990), “ The Effects of Exchange Rate Changes on Prices and Quantities in U.S. Foreign Trade.” International Trade Journal 5 ( 1): 77-92. Deyak, Timothy A., W. Charles Sawyer, and Richard L. Sprinkle (1997), “Changes in the Price and Income Elasticities of U.S. Import Demand.” Economia Internazionale 50(2): 161-175. Dimaranan, Betina, and Robert McDougall, and Thomas Hertel (1998), “Behavioral Parameters.” In McDougall, Robert, Aziz Elbehri, and Truong P. Thruong (eds.), Global Trade, Assistance, and Protection: The GT AP 4 Data Base. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Dixit, Avinash, and Joseph E. Stiglitz (1977), “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity.” American Economic Review 67 (3): 297-307. 140 Engen, Eric M., and William G. Gale (1996), “The Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform on Saving.” In Henry J. Aaron and William G. Gale (eds.), Economic Efi'ects of Fundamental Tax Reform. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Engen, Eric M., and William G. Gale (1997), “Macroeconomic Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform: Simulations With a Stochastic Life-Cycle, Overlapping Generations, General Equilibrium Model.” In Joint Committee on Taxation Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, prepared and compiled by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. Washington, DC: USGPO (November). Fehr, Hans, Christoph Rosenberg, and Wolfgang Wiegard (1995), Welfare Eflects of Value-Added Tax Harmonization in Europe: A Computational General Equilibrium Analysis, Springer-Verlag. F eldstein, Martin S. (1994), “Tax Policy and International Capital Flows.” Weltwirtschaflliches Archiv 130 (4): 675-697. F eldstein, Martin S., and Charles Horioka (1980), “Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows.” Economic Journal 90: 314-329. Frankel, Jeffrey A. (1990), “Quantifying International Capital Mobility in the 19805.” In B. Douglas Bernheim and John B. Shoven (eds.), National Saving and Economic Performance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. French, Kenneth R., and James M. Poterba (1991), “Investor Diversification and International Equity Markets.” American Economic Review 81: 222-226. Fuchs, V. R., A. B. Krueger, and James M. Poterba (1998), “Economists’ Views about Parameters, Values, and Policies: Survey Results in Labor and Public Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36: 1387-1425. Fullerton, Don, and Diane L. Rogers (1993), Who Bears the Lifetime Tax Burden ?. Washington D. C.: The Brookings Institution. Fullerton, Don, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley (1983), “Replacing the U.S. Income Tax with a Progressive Consumption Tax.” Journal of Public Economics 20 (February): 3-23. Fullerton, Don, A. Thomas King, John B. Shoven, and John Whalley (1981), “Corporate Tax Integration in the United States: A General Equilibrium Approach.” American Economic Review 71 (September): 677-691. GAMS Development Corporation (1998), Economic Equilibrium Modeling with GAMS - An Introduction to GAMS/MCP and GAMS/MPSGE, November. 141 rt?- 02 F’sWI-ah .1 ‘ET‘L- . Gehlhar, M. J ., D. Gray, T. W. Hertel, K. Huff, E. Ianchovichina, B. J. MacDonald, R. McDougall, M. E. Tsigas, and R. Wigle (1996), “Overview of the GTAP Data base.” In T. W. Hertel (ed.), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gordon Roger H., and A. Lans Bovenberg (1996), “Why is Capital So Irnmobile Internationally? Possible Explanations and Implications for Capital Income Taxation”, American Economic Review 86 (5): 1057-1075. Goulder, Lawrence H., John B. Shoven, and John Whalley (1983), “Domestic Tax Policy and the Foreign Sector: The Importance of Alternative Foreign Sector Formulations to Results from a General Equilibrium Tax Analysis Model.” In Martin Feldstein (ed.), Behavioral Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Gravelle, Jane G., and Kent Smetters (1998), “Who Bears the Burden of the Corporate Tax (And Why)?: The Open Economy Case.” Congressional Budget Office Technical Paper Series 1998-1 (August). Greenwood, Jeremy, and Gregory W. Huffman (1991), “Tax Analysis in a Real- Business-Cycle Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics 27 (2): 167-190. Gruber, Harry, and John Mutti (2000), “Do Taxes Influence Where U.S. Corporations Invest?” National Tax Journal 53 (December): 825-839. Grubert, Harry, and T. Scott Newlon (1995), “The International Implications of Consumption Tax Proposals.” National Tax Journal 48 (December): 619-648. Hall, Robert E., and Dale W. J orgenson (1967), “Tax Policy and Investment Behavior.” American Economic Review 57 (June): 391-414. Hamilton, B., and J. Whalley (1985), “Geographically Discriminatory Trade Arrangements.” Review of Economics and Statistics 67: 446-452. Harberger, Arnold C. (1962), “The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax.” Journal of Political Economy 70 (June): 215-240. Harberger, Arnold C. (1995), “The ABCs of Corporation Tax Incidence: Insights into the Open-Economy Case.” In Tax Policy and Economic Growth. Washington, DC: American Council for Capital Formation, Center for Policy Research. Harrison, W. J ., and K. R. Pearson (1996), “Computing Solutions for Large General Equilibrium Models using GEMPACK.” Computational Economics 9: 83-127. Haynes, Stephen E., and Joe A. Stone (1984), “Cross-Price Effects in Demand Between Exports and Imports.” Journal of Macroeconomics 6 (2): 181-195. 142 Heckman, James J. (1993), “What Has Been Learned about Labor Supply in the Past Twenty Years?” American Economic Review 83: 116-121. Heien, Dale M. (1972), “Demographic Effects and the Multiperiod Consumption Function.” Journal of Political Economy 80: 125-138. Hertel, Tomas W., Elena Ianchovichina, and Bradley J. MacDonald (1997), “Multi- Region General Equilibrium Modeling.” In Francois, J. F. and K. A. Reinert (eds.), Applied Methods for Trade Policy Analysis: A Handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hertel, T. W., and M. E. Tsigas (1996), “Structure of GTAP.” In T.W. Hertel (ed.), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hines, James R., Jr. (1996), “Fundamental Tax Reform in an International Setting.” In Henry J. Aaron and William G. Gale (eds.), Economic Eflects of Fundamental Tax Reform. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Japan Statistics Bureau (2001), Japan Statistical Yearbook 2001. Management and Coordination Agency and Government of Japan. J omini, P., J. F. Zeitsch, R. McDougall, A. Welsh, S. Brown, J. Hambley, and J. Kelly (1991), SALT ER: A General Equilibrium Model of the World Economy, Vol. 1. Model Structure, Database and Parameters. Canberra, Australia: Industry Commission. J orgenson, Dale W., and Peter J. Wilcoxen (1997), “The Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform and the Feasibility of Dynamic Revenue Estimation.” In Joint Committee on Taxation Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, prepared and compiled by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. Washington, DC: USGPO (November). J orgenson, Dale W., and Peter J. Wilcoxen (1998), “The Economic Impact of Fundamental Tax Reform.” Paper presented at the Fourth Annual Conference of the James A. Baker III Institute for Public Policy, Rice University. November 5. Keller, W. J. (1980), Tax Incidence: A General Equilibrium Approach, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Killingsworth, Mark R. (1983), Labor Supply. New York: Cambridge University Press. Mendoza, Enrique G., Assaf Razin, and Linda L. Tesar (1994), “Effective Tax Rates in Macroeconomics. Cross-country Estimates of Tax Rates on Factor Incomes and Consumption.” Journal of Monetary Economics 34: 297-323. 143 Mendoza, Enrique G., and Linda L. Tesar (1998), “The International Rarnification of Tax Reforms: Supply-Side Economics in a Global Economy.” American Economic Review 88 (1): 226-245. Messere Ken (ed., 1998), The Tax System in Industrialized Countries. Oxford University Press. Mieszkowski, Peter, and George R. Zodrow (eds.), (forthcoming, 2002), United States Tax Reform in the 21 " Century. Cambridge, England, and New York: Cambridge University Press. Moffett, Michael H. (1989), “The J -Curve Revisited: An Empirical Examination of the United States.” Journal of International Money and Finance 8 (3): 427-444. OECD (1995), Revenue Statistics of OECD Member Countries, 1 965-1994. OECD (1995), OECD Economic Surveys, 1994-1995, France. OECD (1996), OECD Economic Surveys, 1995-1996, Germany. OECD (1999), National Accounts: Main Aggregates, 1960-1997. Obstfeld, Maurice (1993), “International Capital Mobility in the 19905.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4534 (November). Pi ggott, J. R., and John Whalley (1985), UK. Tax Policy and Applied General Equilibrium Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Reinert, Kenneth A. and David W. Roland-Holst (1992), “Amrington Elasticities for United States Manufacturing Sectors.” Journal of Policy Modeling 14 (5): 631- 639. Rogers, Diane Lim (1997), “Assessing the Effects of Fundamental Tax Reform With the F ullerton-Rogers General Equilibrium Model.” In Joint Committee on Taxation Tax Modeling Project and 1997 Tax Symposium Papers, prepared and compiled by the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation. Washington, DC: USGPO (November). Rutherford, Thomas F. (1998), GT APinGAMS: The Dataset and Static Model. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Colorado. Sawyer, W. Charles, and Richard L. Sprinkle (1999), The Demand for Imports and Exports in the World Economy. Vermont: Ashgate Publishing Company. 144 Shiells, Clinton R., and Kenneth A. Reinert (1993), “Armington Models and Terrns-of- Trade Effects: Some econometric Evidence for North America.” Canadian Journal of Economics 26 (2): 299-316. Shoven, John B. (1976), “The Incidence and efficiency Effects of Taxes on Income From Capital.” Journal of Political Economy 84 (December): 1261-1283. Shoven, John B., and John Whalley (1972), “A General Equilibrium Calculation of the Effects of Differential Taxation of Income from Capital in the U.S.” Journal of Public Economics 1: 281-322. Shoven, John B., and John Whalley (1992), Applying General Equilibrium. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. Slemrod, Joe] (1983), “A General Equilibrium Model of Taxation with Endogenous Financial Behavior.” In M. F eldstein (ed.), Behavior Simulation Methods in Tax Policy Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Slernrod, Joel (1990), “Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: Evidence from a Cross-Country Comparison.” In Razin, A., and J. Slernrod (eds.), Taxation in the Global Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Spence, M. E. (1976), “Product Selection, Fixed Costs, and Monopolistic Competition.” Journal of International Economics 43: 217-236. Stern, Robert M., Christopher F. Baum, and Mark N. Greene (1979), “Evidence on Structural Change in the Demand for Aggregate U.S. Imports and Exports.” Journal of Political Economy 87 (1): 179-192. Stern, Robert M., Jonathan Francis, and Bruce Schumacher (1976), Price Elasticities in International Trade. An Annotated Bibliography. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd.. Summers, Lawrence H. (1981), “Capital Taxation and Accumulation in a Life Cycle Growth Model.” American Economic Review 71: 533-544. Taylor, Lester D. (1971), “Saving Out of Different Types of Income.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 383-415. Thalrnann, Philippe, Lawrence H. Goulder, and Francois DeLorme (1996), “Assessing the International Spillover Effects of Capital Income Taxation.” International Tax and Public Finance 3: 449-478. Tsigas, M. E., T. W. Hertel, and J. K. Binkley (1992), “Estimates of Systematic Reporting Biases in Trade Statistics.” Economic Systems Research 44: 297-310. 145 United Nations (1999), National Accounts Statistics: Main Aggregates and Detailed Tables, 1 995 . U.S. Department of Commerce (1998), Survey of Current Business 78 (August). Whalley, John (1975), “A General Equilibrium Assessment of the 1973 United Kingdom Tax Reform.” Economica 42: 139-161. Whalley, John (1980), “Discriminatory Features of Domestic Factor Tax System in a Goods Mobile-Factors Immobile Trade Model: An Empirical General Equilibrium Approach.” The Journal of Political Economy 88 (6): 1177-1202. Whalley, John (1982), “An Evaluation of the Recent Tokyo Round Trade Agreement Using General Equilibrium Computational Methods.” Journal of Policy Modeling 4: 341-361. Whalley, John (1985), Trade Liberalization among Major World Trading Areas, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 146