LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 cJCIRCIDateDuo.p65-p.15 MONEY, JUDGES, AND VOTES: THE EFFECTS OF CAMPAIGN SPENDING IN STATE SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS By Christopher William Bonneau A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 2002 ABSTRACT MONEY, JUDGES, AND VOTES: THE EFFECTS OF CAMPAIGN SPENDING IN STATE SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS By Christopher William Bonneau This dissertation is about campaign spending in state supreme court elections. Specifically, I examine whether campaign spending by candidates for the state high court bench promotes or inhibits electoral competition. Looking at all contested state supreme court elections from 1990-2000, I find that, in some circumstances, campaign spending promotes competition, while in other cases it retards it. The effects of campaign spending on the vote total depend upon characteristics of the candidates, the state electoral context, and institutional arrangements. The results both extend current findings about the role of campaign spending in congressional and state legislative elections, and speak to efforts currently underway in state legislatures to reform or eradicate judicial elections. Dedicated to my parents, Edmund and J acklyn Bonneau iii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This dissertation could not have been written without the assistance of several people. First, I would like to thank my dissertation committee of Melinda Gann Hall (Chair), Paul Brace, Darren Davis, and Dave Rohde. By consistently challenging me and being accessible to listen to my ideas, these individuals greatly improved the dissertation. This project would not have been possible without the financial support of the National Science Foundation (Grant: SES 0108906). I would also like to thank the Department of Political Science at Michigan State University for providing an ideal environment in which to attain a quality graduate education. I am grateful to the Departments of Political Science at the University of Pittsburgh, Northern Illinois University, and the University of North Texas for inviting me to present portions of this project. I received many useful suggestions and ideas on those trips. Several fellow graduate students and faculty members (both at Michigan State and elsewhere) were invaluable for their advice, criticisms, and general friendship. I truly appreciate the contributions of: Charles Finocchairo, Martha Humphries Ginn, Wonjae Hwang, Mark Hurwitz, Matt Kleiman, Laura Langer, Mark Souva, and Rebecca Tothero. Finally, and most importantly, I could not have asked for a better mentor than Melinda Gann Hall. Her advice, suggestions, constructive criticisms, support, and patience were invaluable to the completion of this dissertation. Her support throughout my four years at Michigan State was strong and constant, and her professional career is one I can only hope to model. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ........................................................................................ viii Chapter 1: Introduction: Electing Judges ......................................................... 1 The Brief History of Electing Judges ...................................................... 3 State Supreme Court Elections and Democratic Theory .............................. 10 The Climate of State Supreme Court Elections ......................................... 15 Research Question .......................................................................... 17 Plan of the Dissertation .................................................................... 19 Chapter 2: Money and State Supreme Court Elections ....................................... 20 Money and the Composition of the Bench ............................................. 20 Money and the Actors in Judicial Elections ............................................ 22 The Role and Importance of Institutional Structures .................................. 27 The Role and Importance Of Candidates ................................................. 31 Conclusion .................................................................................. 35 Chapter 3: Research Design, Data, and Method ................................................ 37 The Importance of Comparative Research .............................................. 37 Research Design ............................................................................. 40 Data ........................................................................................... 44 Method ....................................................................................... 46 Conclusion ................................................................................... 51 Chapter 4: Describing State Supreme Court Elections ......................................... 52 State Supreme Court Elections Over Time .............................................. 52 Partisan versus Nonpartisan Elections .................................................... 62 State-by-State Comparisons ................................................................ 67 Conclusion ................................................................................... 74 Chapter 5: Explaining Campaign Spending ..................................................... 75 Specifying the Model ...................................................................... 75 Estimation Technique ..................................................................... 81 The Determinants of Campaign Spending .............................................. 84 Conclusion .................................................................................. 88 Chapter 6: The Effects of Money on Votes: Non-Institutional Model ...................... 89 Specifying the Models ..................................................................... 90 Specification ................................................................................ 98 Estimation Technique ..................................................................... 99 The Role of Money in State Supreme Court Elections ............................... 103 The Role of Independent Expenditures ................................................ 109 Conclusion ................................................................................. 1 12 Chapter 7: The Effects of Money on Votes: Institutional Model .......................... 114 Institutional Variables .................................................................... 114 Estimation Technique .................................................................... 119 The Role of Money and Institutions in State Supreme Court Elections ............................................................................. 119 The Role of Money and Institutions in State Supreme Court Elections: Selection System, Electoral Constituency and Term of Office ........................................................................ 129 vi The Role Of Independent Expenditures ................................................ 147 Conclusion ................................................................................. 151 Chapter 8: Conclusion ............................................................................ 152 Summary Of Results ...................................................................... 152 The Importance of Electoral Competition ............................................. 155 State Supreme Court Election Reform ................................................. 157 Future Research ........................................................................... 160 Appendix ............................................................................................ 163 References .......................................................................................... 175 vii LIST OF TABLES Table 1.1: Institutional Arrangements for States That Elect Their Justices, 2000 .......................................................................................... 9 Table 4.1: Total Average Spending by Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 (number of elections in parentheses) ................................................ 53 Table 4.2: Total Average Spending by Year in 1990 dollars, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 (number of elections in parentheses) .................................... 55 Table 4.3: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 ....................................................................... 57 Table 4.4: Average Percentage of the Vote by Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 ............................................................................................. 59 Table 4.5: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 .......................................................... 61 Table 4.6: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by Method of Selection, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 .......................................... 63 Table 4.7: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and Method of Selection, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 ......................................... 66 Table 4.8: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by State, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 .......................................................... 69 Table 4.9: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and State, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 (number of elections in parentheses) ............. 72 Table 5.1: Variable Descriptions for a Model of Campaign Spending in State Supreme Court Elections ........................................................................... 80 Table 5.2: Variable Descriptions for the Selection Model of Campaign Spending in State Supreme Court Elections ................................................................. 83 Table 5.3: Predicting Campaign Spending ...................................................... 85 Table 6.1: Variable Descriptions for a Model of Electoral Competition in State Supreme Court Elections ........................................................................... 97 viii Table 6.2: The Effects Of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests ............................................................................................ 104 Table 6.3: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats ...................................... 107 Table 6.4: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted ...................................... 110 Table 6.5: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted ...................................................................... 111 Table 7.1: Additional Variable Descriptions for a Model of Electoral Competition in State Supreme Court Elections .............................................. 118 Table 7.2: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests .............................................................................................. 120 Table 7.3: Comparison of Non-Institutional and Institutional Models of Incumbent-Challenger Contests .................................................................. 124 Table 7.4: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats ..................................... 126 Table 7.5: Comparison of Non-Institutional and Institutional Models Of Open Seat Contests ................................................................................ 128 Table 7.6: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Selection System Interaction Terms .............................................. 130 Table 7.7: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with District Interaction Terms .......................................................... 131 Table 7.8: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Multi-Member Interaction Terms .................................................... 132 Table 7.9: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Term Interaction Terms ............................................................. 133 Table 7.10: The Effects of Term Length on Spending, Incumbent- Challenger Contests ............................................................................... 137 Table 7.11: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Selection System Interaction Terms ........................................................................ 140 Table 7.12: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with District Interaction Terms .................................................................................. 141 Table 7.13: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Multi- Member Interaction Terms ....................................................................... 142 Table 7.14: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Term Interaction Terms .................................................................................. 143 Table 7.15: The Effects of Term Length on Spending, Open Seat Races ................................................................................................. 146 Table 7.16: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted ..................................... 148 Table 7.17: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted ....................................................... 149 Table A.1: OLS Results for Table 5.3 .......................................................... 164 Table A2: Hausman Test Results for Table 6.2 .............................................. 165 Table A3: Hausman Test Results for Table 6.3 .............................................. 166 Table A4: OLS Results for Table 6.2 .......................................................... 167 Table A5: OLS Results for Table 6.3 .......................................................... 168 Table A6: OLS Results for Table 6.4 ......................................................... 169 Table A.7: OLS Results for Table 6.5 ......................................................... 170 Table A8: Chow Test Results for Table 7.2 .................................................. 171 Table A9: Hausman Test Results for Table 7.2 ............................................. 172 Table A.10: Hausman Test Results for Table 7.4 ............................................. 173 Table A. 1 1: OLS Results for Table 7.2 ........................................................ 174 CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION: ELECTING JUDGES The 2001 race for the Louisiana Supreme Court was one of the most contentious (and expensive) in the history of the state (Swerczek 2001). Democrat Court of Appeals Judge John Weimer faced off against fellow Democrat (and district court judge) Mary Hotard Becnel. The winner of the election would sit on the court for the final year of retired Justice Harry Lemmon’s term before running for reelection in 2002. Court Observers saw this election as having the potential to affect the balance of the court between the pro-trial lawyer forces (who supported Becnel) and the pro-business troops (who supported Weimer). While the race was conducted with civility, and turnout was Ii ght, both candidates campaigned vigorously for the seat (Swerczek 2001). Despite spending only $272,000 (compared with Becnel’s $828,000), Weimer won the race with 51% of the vote. What factors contributed to Weimer’s victory? Are these factors consistent across all elections for open seats? In this election for an open seat, the candidate who spent the most money did not win the election. Does this mean that spending is unrelated to electoral success in open seat elections? The 2000 elections for the Alabama Supreme Court were some of the most expensive (and bitter) in state supreme court election history (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002; Omdorff 2002). With five seats up for election, both sides of the tort reform battle (pro-business interests and trial lawyers) saw this as a perfect opportunity to solidify support for their cause on the court. Republicans won both open seats (Roy Moore defeated Sharon Yates and Robert Harwood defeated Joel Laird), and the one Republican incumbent (Champ Lyons) was reelected easily. Incumbent Ralph Cook, a Democrat, was ousted by Republican Lyn Stuart, 3 Circuit Court judge. Stuart spent $1,254,450 on her campaign, outspending Cook, who only spent $437,482. Incumbent John Henry England (Democrat) did not fare much better. He lost his reelection bid to Thomas Woodall, a Republican Circuit Court Judge. England spent $500,681 on his reelection bid, an amount dwarfed by the $1,107,839 spent by Woodall. Did the amount Of money spent by Stuart and Woodall have anything to do with the defeat of Justices Cook and England? Did Stuart and Woodall spend enough money to overcome the advantages of incumbency? Or was the election decided along ideological and partisan lines, with the Republican candidates winning in a decidedly Republican state? In the 2000 Ohio state supreme court elections, Justice Alice Robie Resnick, a Democrat, was targeted for defeat by pro-business interests. She was challenged by Court of Appeals Judge Terrence O’Donnell. Despite the Chamber of Commerce (and other similar groups) spending over $5 million on the campaign, Resnick won with 56% of the vote (Brown 2000). At the same time, Justice Deborah Cook, a Republican, won a less contentious race over Municipal Court Judge Timothy Black. Taken together, do these results mean that campaign spending does not matter, at least where incumbents are concerned? Does the incumbency advantage trump spending in nonpartisan states? Are there differences between the effects of spending in partisan and nonpartisan states? How else can these results be explained? This dissertation examines the relationship between electoral competition and the amount of money spent by candidates in state supreme court elections. The election of judges is one of the most interesting, and distinctive, facts Of American political life. Voters in forty-three states elect state court judges at some level (Carp and Stidham 2001), and thirty-eight states have some form of election for their justices on the state supreme court. Despite the fact that a majority of state court judges are elected, we know little about the factors that determine the outcomes of these elections. This dissertation represents one of the first comprehensive, systematic forays into this topic. The Brief History of Electing Judges The election of judges is an almost uniquely American phenomenon (Schotland 1985). The early American states selected judges much like their former British rulers: they were appointed for life terms (although there were often provisions for impeachment).l Some states had the judges appointed by the legislatures, while others provided for gubernatorial appointment. In short, the selection of state court judges paralleled the selection of federal judges (Sheldon and Maule 1997). Originally, judges were selected in this way because the judiciary was considered a weak institution. Consequently, courts were extremely deferential to legislatures, since they were heavily dependent on them (Sheldon and Maule 1997). Interestingly, now selection schemes like this are touted as promoting the independence of judges from both the electorate and other political actors. Judges should be free to interpret the law and make judicial decisions independent of as many constraints and political factors as possible. Being appointed by the governor or legislature for a life-term frees judges from ' Of the twelve states that currently appoint justices to the high court bench, only one (Hawaii) is not one of the original states of the union, or is a state that was once part of one of the original states (Maine was initially part of Massachusetts, and Vermont was originally part of New York. Both Maine and Vermont have their governor appoint their state supreme court justices.) Further, only two of the original thirteen states have true elections for the state supreme court (Georgia and North Carolina). paying attention to factors irrelevant to their jobs as judges.2 By not conditioning their continued employment on things like elections, judges will be free to interpret the law and make rulings based on legal criteria (such as the facts of the case, the law, and precedent) and not on how they think the public will react. It is important to note that proponents are appointed schemes are not really arguing for complete “independence” from all political actors. As was discussed above, judges who are appointed (and need to be reappointed) can hardly be said to be independent from the appointing authority (legislature, governor, or both). Thus, the “independence” argument is really an argument for independence from the electorate. Certainly, with the rare exception of those states that provide for life-tenure, judges who are dependent upon either the governor or the legislature for reappointment are not completely “independent.” Presumably, an appointed judge who makes decisions that are contrary to the policy preferences of the actor (or actors) who has (have) the power to reappoint her could be subject to the same sanction as the elected judge who makes decisions contrary to the preferences of the electorate: loss of her job. In fact, this dependence on the legislature or governor (the lack of independence Of judges) was one of the reasons given to move away from the appointment of judges to their election (Sheldon and Maule 1997). The appointment of judges was common until about 1830. This coincided with the demise of the Federalists, and the rise of J acksonian democracy. “J acksonian democracy meant that the average citizen could not only use the extended franchise to 2 Interestingly, many appointive schemes in the states do not have life-tenure for their judges. Indeed, only Rhode Island has such a system, while three other states (Massachusetts, New Hampshire, and New Jersey) have terms of office for this judges that expire when the judges reach age 70. In some other states (such as Delaware, Hawaii, Massachusetts, and Vermont), the governor must limit her selection to one of the candidates recommended by a judicial nominating commission (Hall and Bonneau 2000). pick his leaders, but he could share responsibility for governing” (Sheldon and Maule 1997, 3). In terms of courts, this philosophy led to elected judges and shorter terms of office. There were three primary reasons why judicial elections gained popularity. First, there was the issue of judicial review. Since judges were invalidating laws enacted by the legislature, it was argued that they should be chosen by the electorate, just like the legislature.3 Second, the legal profession hailed the movement toward an elected judiciary, seeing it as “an opportunity to provide the judiciary with its own separate constituency, thus ensuring it some measure of independence from the legislature” (Sheldon and Maule 1997, 4). As an independent branch of government, it was argued that judges should not be agents of the legislature. Third, and finally, popular elections allowed for the removal of incompetent and arrogant judges. While judges could be impeached under appointive schemes, impeachment was thought of as too drastic a punishment, and thus was used sparingly (Friedman 1985, 129—130). The primary motivation for electing judges was that judges are political Officials, and as political officials they should derive their political power from the people, and not from a co-equal branch of government. Indeed, the process of electing judges is the only process that can make them independent from the legislature and governor. Further, competitive elections provide for electoral accountability: judges, like legislators, are accountable to the electorate for their decisions and actions. Judges are thus less likely to be out-of-step with the political climate of their state. After all, supporters of elections would say, if a state provides for capital punishment, why should a judge who refuses to uphold the death penalty be allowed to serve? This judge is refusing to apply the law as 3 It is interesting to note that even states that did not change the method by which they chose judges “added restraint by shortening the terms for judges" (Sheldon and Maule 1997, 4), which also serves to reduce judicial independence, albeit in a different way. it is written, and is substituting her own personal policy preferences for the law. While it would be extremely difficult to remove this judge in an appointed state, the voters can remove this renegade judge in her next election. Critics of judicial elections make two central arguments. First, they claim that judges should not be held accountable to the electorate. Judging is not an intrinsically political act like legislating, and judges should not be penalized by the electorate for their rulings (e. g., Marks and Hoke 2001; Mikva and Sessions 2001; Pittsburgh Post-Gazette 2001a, 2001c; Wenzel 2001). Second, and relatedly, opponents of judicial elections argue that even if it were conceded that electing judges is not, de facto, inappropriate, in their current form judicial elections are ineffective mechanisms for holding judges accountable. Specifically, Reforrners argue that partisan elections, characterized by lackluster campaigns devoid of issue content, are disconnected from substantive evaluations of candidates or other meaningful considerations relevant to the judiciary, which renders them ineffective as a means of accountability (Hall 2001a, 316) Regardless of whether judges should, or should not, be independent from the electorate, the debate is irrelevant if elections fail to provide electoral competition, a necessary component electoral accountability. In response to criticisms like these, judicial elections have undergone two significant evolutions since the 1830’s. First, while judicial elections were initially partisan, there soon became allegations of corruption and control of the bench by political machines. Around 1900, Progressives began pushing for judicial elections to be nonpartisan. In these types of elections, candidates would run in a competitive election, but without party labels. Supporters of nonpartisan elections argue that they provide for electoral accountability, while not subjecting judges to the vagaries of partisan tides. Thus, voters are able to remove a judge from office, but a judge will not be removed simply by belonging to the wrong political party. By removing partisan considerations, the hope was that more qualified jurists would be elected to the bench.4 However, removing partisan labels had the effect, perhaps unintended, of making these races less competitive (see Chapters 4 and 7). By taking a crucial piece of information away from the voters, states electing their judges on nonpartisan ballots served to strengthen the incumbency advantage. Thus, not only are judges independent from the legislature (since they are elected), but they are also less accountable to the electorate (because the elections are less competitive). A second reform, first proposed around 1913, is commonly referred to as “merit selection.” While there are several variations of this selection scheme, in its most common form a justice would be initially appointed to the bench by the governor (from a list of names—usually three—submitted by a nominating commission) and this justice would serve for a period of time (usually one or two years) before facing the voters in a nonpartisan retention election. Voters would then be asked, “Should Judge X be retained?” If the judge received more “yes” votes than “no,” then she would retain her seat and serve for a fixed period of time (6 to 12 years, depending on the state) before facing the voters again. If the justice was defeated, then the governor would fill the 4 Interestingly, the Progressives appear to be wrong on both counts. Glick and Emmert (1987) and Bonneau (2001a) find no difference in the quality of judges between selection systems, and Hall (2001a) finds that nonpartisan elections are driven by political factors, just as partisan elections. However, Schaffner, Streb, and Wright (2001) find that, in local and state legislative elections, voters in nonpartisan elections rely less on partisan cues and more on incumbency. vacancy just as she did originally. Like nonpartisan elections, this was designed to ensure a more qualified bench and remove political considerations from selecting judges.5 Merit selection is by far the system that gives the judges maximum independence from both the legislature and the electorate. Once judges are appointed, they are not dependent on the legislature (or governor) for reappointment. Further, since they run unopposed for retention, they are also, according to all measurable indicators, independent from the electorate. Indeed, these candidates very rarely lose. While presuming to combine the “best” features of appointed (independence) and elected (accountability) schemes, merit selection has the effect of making judges independent from both other political actors (since they are not dependent on them for their reappointment) and the electorate (since they very rarely lose their bids for retention). Thus, the means by which judges are selected has moved from being independent from the electorate but highly dependent on the legislature and governor (appointed), to being accountable to the electorate and independent from the legislature and governor (elections), to being independent from both the legislature and governor and the electorate (merit). In addition to the method by which they select their state supreme court justices, states also vary on other institutional factors, such as term of office, electoral constituency, and structure of the seat. In Table 1.1, the states that elect their high court justices are displayed, along with their current institutional arrangements. 5 The evidence on the success of this plan is similar to the success of nonpartisan elections: there is no evidence of a more qualified bench (Glick and Emmert 1987; Bonneau 2001a), and these races are not immune from political considerations (Hall 2001a). Table 1.1: Institutional Arrangements for States That Elect Their Justices, 2000 State Selection Term of Electoral Seat System Office Constituency Structure Alabama Partisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Alaska Retention 10 Statewide Single-Member Arizona Retention 6 Statewide Single-Member Arkansas Partisan 8 Statewide Single-Member California Retention l2 Statewide Single-Member Colorado Retention 10 Statewide Single-Member Florida Retention 6 Statewide Sligle-Member Georgia Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Idaho Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Illinois Partisan/Retention* 10 District Single—Member Indiana Retention 10 Statewide Single-Member Iowa Retention 8 Statewide Single-Member Kansas Retention 6 Statewide Single-Member Kentucky Nonpartisan 8 District Single-Member Louisiana Partisan 10 District Single-Member Maryland Retention 10 District Single-Member Michigan Nonpartisan" 8 Statewide Multimember Minnesota Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Mississippi Nonpartisan 8 District Single-Member Missouri Retention 12 Statewide Sigh-Member Montana Nonpartisan/Retention*** 8 Statewide smile-Member Nebraska Retention 6 District smile-Member Nevada Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member New Mexico Partisan/Retention*** 8 Statewide Single-Member N. Carolina Partisan 8 Statewide Single-Member N. Dakota Nonpartisan 10 Statewide Single-Member Ohio Nonpartisan“ 6 Statewide Single-Member Oklahoma Retention 6 Statewide Single-Member Oregon Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Pennsylvania Partisan/Retention* 10 Statewide Multimember S. Dakota Retention 8 Statewide Single-Member Tennessee Retention 8 Statewide Single-Member Texas Partisan 6 Statewide Single-Member Utah Retention 10 Statewide Single-Member Washington Nonpartisan 6 Statewide Single-Member W. Virginia Partisan 12 Statewide Multimember Wisconsin Nonpartisan 10 Statewide Single—Member Wyoming Retention 8 Statewide Single-Member * = originally elected in partisan elections; retention elections after initial election ** 2 candidates nominated in partisan primaries/conventions *** _ retention election only if unopposed Regardless of form, elections to the state high court bench have been around since 1830, with no sign of disappearing. Given their importance, and the constant attempts to reform (or eradicate) them, it is more than a little surprising that we know little about these elections. State Supreme Court Elections and Democratic Theory Our lack of knowledge about judicial elections is troublesome, especially since elections are one of the cornerstones of democracy. American democracy is founded (at least in part) on the notion that officials are to be elected by their constituents (Pomper 1968). In states that have elections for state supreme court seats, justices are to be selected by the voters of the state (or district) in which they reside, just as legislators. One of the most important facts about elections is that they provide for competition. That is, they provide the opportunity for voters to choose some candidates over others. This is important because, “[T]he degree to which voters are not offered choices on the ballot raises significant questions about the health of a democracy” (Squire 2000, 131). Competition can be conceptualized in two different ways. First, a necessary condition of competition is simply the presence of alternatives. That is, there must be more than one candidate from which to choose. Thus, under this conceptualization, any election for a seat on the state high court bench is considered “competitive” if more than one candidate seeks the seat. This definition has the advantage of defining a race as competitive before the votes are tallied. Additionally, this recognizes the fact that “[E]ven facing a weak challenger can cause a representative some concern” (Squire 1989a, 283). However, the simplistic nature of this conceptualization is 10 also its biggest drawback; it confuses “competitive” with “contested.” Applying this logic to congressional elections, the 2000 US. Senate race in Massachusetts between Ted Kennedy and Jack Robinson was “competitive,” even though Kennedy won with 73% of the vote. A competitive race must be contested; but a contested race does not have to be competitive. The Kennedy race just mentioned was certainly contested, but could hardly be said to be competitive. An alternative conceptualization of a “competitive” race focuses on the percentage of the vote obtained by both candidates. Under this definition, races can only be said to be “competitive” after the election is complete. The lower the margin of victory for the winner, the more competitive the race. Using this definition, the Kennedy-Robinson race is viewed as less competitive than the 2000 US. Senate race in Michigan between Debbie Stabenow and Spencer Abraham (in which Stabenow won with 49% of the vote), although it is more competitive than if Kennedy were not challenged at all. Instead of conceptualizing “competition” as dichotomous (present or not), this definition views competition as a continuum, with races being more or less competitive, depending on the level of support provided to each candidate by the voters. In this dissertation, I focus on the second definition of competition. The reasons for my choice are simple: I am interested in what factors promote (or inhibit) competitive elections. While one can do this using a dichotomous measure (Bonneau and Hall 2001), doing so requires me to consider the Kennedy and Stabenow races as equivalent—they are both “competitive.” However, I am interested in what makes races more or less competitive. That is, why did Kennedy win so easily, while Stabenow was in a dogfight? More specifically, I focus on the effects of campaign spending on 11 competitiveness. Understanding the electoral process is centered (to some degree) around this question: what factors explain competition, and can competition be promoted (or inhibited) by changing certain conditions? This dissertation focuses on competition in elections to the state high court bench. It is important to study and understand electoral competition because its presence (or absence) serves as a constraint (or lack thereof) on electoral actors. From the congressional literature, we have learned that “[E]ven ‘safe’ representatives who face challengers live with some fear that they may be defeated, and this wariness may constrain their actions” (Squire 1989a, 282). For example, a congressional incumbent who is facing competition in her bid for reelection may feel compelled to support legislation she may otherwise oppose for fear of losing her seat. The more serious the competition, the more constraint she will feel. The same holds true for state supreme court incumbents: The presence of competition may alter her behavior on the bench. In a series of studies, Brace and Hall found that justices alter their behavior in the presence of elections (Brace and Hall 1990, 1995, 1997; Hall 1987, 1992, 1995). “[A]ppointive selection procedures are associated with considerably less dissent [on state supreme courts]” (Brace and Hall 1990, 65; see also Hall 1992). The fact that they have to face the electorate and may be subject to electoral competition alters the behavior of state supreme court justices on the bench. More fundamentally than dissent rates, Hall (1995, 498) finds that, “The willingness of supreme court justices actually to condemn individual defendants to death may rest, at least to some extent, on general electoral conditions and the justices’ individual experiences with electoral politics.” Likewise, the frequency of facing the 12 voters affects behavior on the bench: “[T]he political result of shorter terms of office is a decidedly more conservative bench, at least on the issue of the death penalty” (Brace and Hall 1997, 1223; see also Brace and Hall 1995). These examples point to the fundamental importance of studying electoral competition: competition is essential for elected officials to behave in a way congruent with the preferences of the electorate. The more competitive the election, the more congruent a justice’s behavior will be with the electorate. Elections provide the opportunity for the public to control the composition of the state supreme court bench (and thus, indirectly, the outcome of cases); competitive elections are the realization of this provision. This explains the findings by Hall (1995) that justices are more willing to uphold capital punishment sentences based on their proximity to reelection. It is important to note that what has been found to affect the behavior of actors seeking election or reelection is solely due to the presence of competition. It has little to do with what the electorate knows, or does not know, about the candidates. A competitive election can be an effective mechanism by which to affect behavior even in the absence of knowledge by the voters. “[E]ven in situations Of incomplete information, there are powerful equilibrating forces pushing public policy in the direction of the representation of public sentiment” (Ferejohn 1990, 5). All that is required is that the voters are minimally concerned about the acts of the political actors (Key 1961; Pomper 1968; Ferejohn 1990). Indeed, “[T]he voter need not know what is wise, but only what is personally satisfactory or obnoxious” (Pomper 1968, 39; see also Key 1961, 467). Thus, despite the fact that voters are often ignorant both of the issues and the candidates (Key 1961), competition is vital to efficacious elections, if for no other reason than because it 13 is by the electoral process that voters can retain or remove Officials. Voters “can quickly and bloodlessly dismiss an offensive official and thereby end his power, prestige, and profit. No explanations need be given by the electorate, and no appeal can be taken from its decisions (Pomper 1968, 254). For this to be true, there must be competition. Clearly, electoral competition is vital for elections maintaining their legitimacy and fulfilling their raison d’etre: allowing voters to choose their elected officials and holding these officials accountable for their actions. While the necessity of competition is clear, it is less clear how competition can be promoted. By the same token, while we know much about the determinants of competition in congressional and state legislative elections, these processes remain unknown in state supreme court elections. In this dissertation, I focus on one key potential influence on competition in state supreme court elections: campaign spending. To the extent that state supreme court election competitiveness is affected by campaign spending, then the ability of the electorate to make meaningful choices is compromised. This dissertation has very practical implications for the debate over campaign finance regulation currently raging in both state legislatures and the US. Congress. If campaign spending by incumbents is directly related to their percentage of the vote in a positive manner, then incumbent spending will serve to decrease competition, and add to the already large advantages enjoyed by incumbent (see Jacobson 1997, 19-34 for a summary of this literature). Similarly, if spending by challengers erodes the incumbent’s percentage of the vote (and thus boosts the electoral support of the challenger), then campaign spending would serve to promote competition. By limiting the amount of money raised (and thus spent), states will serve to further strengthen the electoral position 14 of incumbents. The same holds true for candidates for open seats: campaign spending may either promote or inhibit competition, and the states can structure these effects by the types of campaign finance laws adopted. Finally, it may be the case the campaign spending has no effect on competition, which means that promoters (and detractors) of competition in judicial elections will have to look elsewhere for ways to either promote or discourage competition. Also unknown is what effects, if any, institutional arrangements have in structuring these relationships: Does it matter if the election is partisan or nonpartisan? Occurs statewide or in a district? Occurs in a single-member district or a multi-member district? At any rate, understanding the effects of spending on electoral outcomes is necessary before measures intended to increase, or decrease, the competitiveness of elections can be seriously considered. The Climate of State Supreme Court Elections To say that state supreme court elections, and the funding thereof, is a popular political issue is an understatement. There has been an abundance of proposed legislation, press coverage, and rhetoric about judicial elections in recent years. In every state that elects judges to its high court bench, legislators, candidates, and the opinion pages of local newspapers have called for either radical reform of the electoral process or the eradication of judicial elections altogether. In December of 2000, the Chief Justices of fifteen states, as well as others interested in the politics of judicial elections, gathered in Chicago at a special summit to discuss issues plaguing the conduct of judicial elections. This meeting, which culminated in a Call to Action, was primarily designed to address the “growing concerns about the 15 million dollar war chests, attack advertising and even outright distortion of an opponent’s record that seems to have become more widespread ...” (Glaberson 2000b, 1).6 This summit comes on the heels of two 60 Minutes stories (1987, 1998), a F rontline investigation (1999), and countless law review articles and other reports in the popular media, all of which assume a strong, direct link between campaign expenditures and election outcomes (American Bar Association 1998; Hansen 1998; Glaberson 2000a, 2000b). Most recently, the Justice at Stake campaign released a report on the 2000 judicial elections. This report, which examines contributions and expenditures in all states that conducted state supreme court elections in 2000, concludes that [T]he year 2000 signaled a dangerous turning point for America’s courts, documenting the growing systematic, and unprecedented infusion of big money and special interest pressure into the election of Supreme Court justices across the country (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002, 4). The report links the increased campaign fundraising and expenditures to the compromising of the fair and impartial administration of justice. Indeed, it states that, “2002 could be a decisive year for the struggle to keep courts fair and impartial” (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002, 4). The report further implores both politicians and voters to help stem back the tide of expensive and contentious campaigns for the state high court bench, else “the threat to fair and impartial justice will grow, perhaps rapidly” (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002, 6). It is not just judges and the media who are calling for the reform or elimination of judicial elections. Governors in states such as Michigan (Bell 2001; Dickerson 2001a) and Pennsylvania (Pittsburgh Post-Gazette 2001b) are proposing replacing elections for 6 The papers presented at this summit, as well as the Call to Action, were subsequently published in the June 2001 Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review. 16 the state high court with appointments by the governor. The state legislatures in Wisconsin and North Carolina are considering providing full public campaign financing for some candidates (Glaberson 2001). Further, some states have even changed the method by which they select supreme court justices, at least in part to insulate members of those courts from the electorate and the rigors of campaigning for office. Since the 1960’s, sixteen states have changed their method of selecting supreme court justices (Hall 2001a). Moreover, some states have changed their selection system quite recently. In the mid-1990’s, Mississippi changed from partisan elections to nonpartisan elections, and Tennessee moved from partisan elections to retention elections. Additionally, Arkansas moved from a partisan election scheme to nonpartisan elections, a change that takes effect in 2002. Clearly, the issue of judicial elections (and the funding thereof) is one that is occupying increasing amounts of time on the public and legislative agenda. Underlying many of these claims is that the amount of campaign spending serves to decrease electoral competition. That is, opponents of judicial elections claim that elections are being won by the candidate who spends the most money, and the more money that is spent, the larger the electoral victory. It thus becomes even more important to systematically examine and understand the dynamics of these elections, especially since states are changing their methods of selection on the basis of untested, unverified claims. Research Question Former North Carolina Supreme Court Chief Justice Henry Frye recently said, “‘Someone needs to do a careful analysis to find out exactly what things make a 17 difference in judicial elections’” (Berry 2001, 37). This dissertation is about electoral competition in state supreme court elections. I am interested in what factors promote or retard electoral competition for the state high court bench. Central to my analysis is the role of campaign spending in these elections. Specifically, I ask: Does campaign spending affect the percentage of the vote received by state supreme court candidates? In order to answer this question, I examine all contested elections for the state high court bench between 1990-2000. This is an important question for the reasons detailed above: allegations abound about the negative effects of campaign spending on the electoral process. However, none of these claims have been tested in any systematic manner. It may in fact be the case that campaign spending decreases competition, and the more money spent by the winner of the election, the larger her percentage of the vote will be. Alternatively, it may be the case that campaign spending promotes competition. The more money that is spent, the higher voter awareness of the candidates and their respective positions will be, especially for candidates who are relatively unknown. This would serve to weaken the incumbency advantage (as well as other advantages such as name recognition), and lead to more competitive races. Further, these effects may vary depending on the type of candidate (incumbent or non-incumbent) as well as the institutional setting in which the election is occurring. Addressing competition in state supreme court elections is essential to a complete understanding of both the electoral and judicial process. 18 Plan of the Dissertation In Chapter 2, I lay out a general argument about electoral competition and the influence of campaign spending in state supreme court elections. Why should we expect money to matter in these elections? What is it about campaign spending that should make it so relevant to electoral outcomes? My research design, data, and method are discussed in Chapter 3. In addition to specifying my design, I also discuss the procurement of the data used in this project, as well as my methodology for assessing the effects of money on votes. Chapter 4 describes the context of state supreme court elections in the time period studied here (1990-2000). Here, I look at patterns of competition and spending, and break them down by year, selection system, type of election, and state. Chapter 5 examines the determinants of campaign spending in state supreme court elections. What factors promote campaign spending, and which factors retard it? Are these factors the same factors that determine electoral competition? In chapters 6 and 7, I empirically assess the influence of campaign spending on election outcomes. In Chapter 6, I look at elections more generally, while in Chapter 7 I explore the institutional differences between state supreme court elections. Does it matter if the election is partisan or nonpartisan? District or statewide? Single- or multi- member district? Drawing on the theory developed in this chapter as well as Chapter 2, I specify multivariate models designed to uncover the influence of campaign spending on state supreme court elections. Finally, in Chapter 8, I summarize the major results of the dissertation, as well as discuss some directions that future studies should pursue. 19 CHAPTER 2 MONEY AND STATE SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS This dissertation focuses on competition and the role of money in state supreme court elections. Specifically, I examine the relationship between candidates, contributors, and voters. State supreme court elections, like elections for all other offices, revolve around these three actors. Further, the relationships between these actors may vary depending on institutional and political context. That is, the relationships between candidates, contributors, and voters may be different in partisan elections compared to nonpartisan elections, single-member seats compared to multi-member seats, statewide elections compared to district elections, or highly electorally competitive states compared to less electorally competitive states. Money and the Composition of the Bench Most fundamentally, elections dictate who will sit on the state supreme court bench. Hall (2001a, 326) has shown that the outcomes of judicial elections are shaped by “candidate- and issue-based forces.” Additionally, Bonneau and Hall (2000, 2001) have shown that not only does the presence of a quality challenger decrease the incumbent’s percentage of the vote, but also that the presence of a challenger (and quality challenger) can be understood in predictable ways. However, none of these studies considers the role of campaign expenditures. That is, we do not know if the amount of money spent by candidates in state supreme court elections affects their electoral support, and thus serves to promote or discourage electoral competition. Further, we do not know the extent to 20 which the influence of campaign spending varies under different institutional arrangements. It is important to understand the effects of campaign spending on state supreme court electoral outcomes because campaign spending may influence electoral results in unforeseen and unintended ways. On one side of the debate over the funding of elections are those who argue that campaign spending is a form of free speech and thus that campaign spending ought not, and cannot, be constitutionally regulated. Further, it is believed that “[m]ore speech means more information, and more information produces an enlightened and active citizenry” (Coleman and Manna 2000, 757; see also Palda 1994; Smith 1996, 1999; Brubaker 1998). This is especially important in judicial elections since these elections are characterized by low levels of information and saliency to the electorate (Klots 1955; Johnson, Schaefer, and McKnight 1978; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1979, 1984; Griffin and Horan 1979; Schotland 1985; Aspin and Hall 1987, 1989; Champagne and Thielemann 1991; Jackson and Riddlesperger 1991; Moog 1992; Arrington 1996; Reid 1996; Klein and Baum 2001). Viewed in this way, campaign spending by candidates can have positive as well as negative effects and may lead to more competitive elections, since the more information voters have about both candidates, the closer the race should be (Jacobson 1980). On the other side of the debate are those who believe that “campaign spending, especially in unlimited amounts, is clearly the bane of democracy” (Coleman and Manna 2000, 758; see also Wertheimer and Manes 1994; Ferguson 1995). These people believe that not only do candidates waste time to campaign and raise money (time that could be better spent performing duties related to their office), but also that incumbents are 21 systematically advantaged and hence electoral competition is reduced.1 Moreover, spending campaign money on “cynical, negative, and misleading campaign advertisements” leads the public to become “distrusting, or, worse, apathetic and uninvolved, and [thus] campaign spending fails to enlighten, engage, or educate the public (Coleman and Manna 2000, 758). That is, not only does campaign spending serve to protect those in office and decrease electoral competition, but it also contributes to the general apathy of the electorate and distrust of the government. While these two views clearly conflict, they do share one assumption: campaign spending affects both the function of elections and electoral outcomes. Both camps argue that campaign spending either promotes or inhibits electoral competition. This dissertation tests this assumption in elections to state supreme courts. Money and the Actors in Judicial Elections Elections are composed of three primary actors: the candidates who are running for office, the contributors to their campaigns, and the voters. Money affects each actor in a different way. Money is a necessary condition for candidates to run for Office (Heard 1960; Alexander 1972; Jacobson 1980). This holds true regardless of the office being sought.2 In order to be competitive, candidates must raise and spend money (Jacobson 1997; Cassie and Breaux 1998). In contested judicial elections between 1990-2000, the mean spending for incumbents was $405,483, while it was $225,740 for challengers. Further, ' Given the high percentage of incumbents that are reelected (Hall 2001a), this is just as true in state supreme court elections as it is in legislative elections. 2 While this statement is truer under some conditions (such as nonpartisan elections), it is no less true for partisan elections. This finding has been confirmed extensively in congressional elections (all of which are partisan), and there is no reason to suspect it would not hold in other partisan elections. 22 the average spending for winners of open seats was $379,908, compared to an average of $283,265 for losers of open seat races. Interestingly, although the minimum amount spent by a challenger who defeated an incumbent was only $500, the mean spending for all challengers who unseated incumbents was $399,717. Why might money be so necessary for success in state supreme court elections? Simply put, money has been found to buy candidates access to voters, both in legislative races (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1990, 1997; Becker and Dunwoody 1982; Green and Krasno 1988, 1990; Squire and Wright 1990; Banaian and Luksetich 1991; Breaux and Gierzynski 1991; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991, 1993, 1996; Squire 1992; Biersack, Hermson, and Wilcox 1993) as well as state supreme court elections (McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1984, 1986a; Thielemann 1993; but see Arrington 1996). While being exposed to a candidate does not necessarily mean that a voter is more likely to vote for that candidate, in general, voters are more likely to vote for candidates with whom they are familiar (Jacobson 1980; Aspin and Hall 1987, 1989; Alvarez 1997). Thus, in this regard, spending money benefits those candidates with whom voters are unfamiliar (generally nonincumbents), and thus promotes competition. With rare exceptions, state supreme court elections take place in a shroud of anonymity and i gnorance.3 Not only are the candidates anonymous, but voters may also be ignorant of the fact that an election is even occurring (Schotland 1985; Arrington 1996). This is especially true in states like Idaho and Wisconsin, where elections for the state supreme court occur in the spring, and not in the fall with elections for other statewide offices. 3 While this is less true in partisan elections (since the voters do have the political party affiliation of the candidates), it is still true to the extent that the candidates themselves are unknown to most of the voters (Champagne and Thielemann 1991). 23 Money therefore allows candidates to publicize their candidacies. This is more important in elections for state supreme court because, unlike elections for governor or congress, candidates for the high court bench do not receive much “free” publicity (Thielemann 1993; Arrington 1996). A candidate for governor can receive free publicity by announcing a new policy initiative, or by criticizing the incumbent. The same is true for candidates seeking a seat in Congress (Jacobson 1980).4 Candidates for the state supreme court are much more restricted in their ability to campaign by the canons of judicial ethics, which prohibit candidates from commenting on cases (and topics) upon which they may eventually decide.5 Hence, while a congressional candidate can receive free news coverage by proposing mandatory life sentences for convicted drug traffickers, a candidate for the state high court cannot (or at least could not, until Republican Party of Minnesota v. White). Further, most state supreme court races have to compete with elections for other state and federal offices. This, coupled with the relative obscurity of state high court candidates in the first place, make publicizing one’s candidacy essential to success—and it makes such publicity expensive. The second actor in state supreme court elections is the contributor. Contributors are the actors who decide to whom to give their money and how much they are going to give. Given the importance of campaign spending to the potential success of a candidate, 4 Gierzynski and Breaux (1991, 1993) find that most candidates for the state legislature also cannot count on receiving much free publicity. 5 Note that the recent United States Supreme Court decision in Republican Party of Minnesota v. White (2002; 247 F 3d 854) invalidates most of these restrictions on candidate speech. Now that candidates running for the state high court bench can campaign much like candidates for other elected offices, the influence of campaign spending may increase (and thus we would also expect the amount of money spent to increase). This is because campaign spending will allow the candidates to provide relevant information to the voters about their views that was previously banned. If spending is effective even when candidates cannot provide much meaningful information, it will be even more effective when meaningful information can be provided. Because spending will be more effective, we would thus expect candidates to raise and spend more money, because it is an easy way to increase their electoral support. 24 contributors play a vital, if not always visible, role in state supreme court elections. There are several possible motivations for contributing money. Some people (or groups) give money to candidates who share a similar ideology or party affiliation (Welch 1979; Gopoian 1984; Su, Neustadtl, and Clawson 1995). In this case, a trial lawyer would donate money to a candidate (likely a Democrat) because they both have a similar philosophy regarding corporate liability and punitive damages. Others are issue-givers; they give money to candidates who agree with them on a particular issue (or issues) (Gopoian 1984; Munger 1989; Hall and Wayman 1990; Grier and Munger 1991; Romer and Snyder 1994). A pro-life organization will give money to those candidates (likely Republicans) who agree with them on restricting a woman’s right to choose. Some give money because they personally know the candidate, or know someone who knows the candidate (Thielemann 1993). And still others are motivated to contribute based on the candidate’s merits; that is, they truly believe that the candidate is the most qualified for thejob. Contributors play a crucial role in the competitiveness of state supreme court elections. Candidates must be able to spend (and thus need to raise) money in order to be competitive. Evidence presented earlier suggests this is even more important for nonincumbent candidates: the viability of their candidacy may depend, to a large extent, on their ability to publicize their candidacy and increase their name recognition with the voters. Contributors play a key role in the electoral process by enabling some candidates (and handicapping others) to be competitive by providing them with one of they key tools they need to be successful: money. 25 The voters are the third actor in state supreme court elections affected by money. To the extent that judicial elections are low information, low-salience elections, the electorate usually possesses little (if any) information on the candidates (Klots 1955; Johnson, Schaefer, and McKnight 1978; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1979, 1984; Griffin and Horan 1979; Schotland 1985; Aspin and Hall 1987, 1989; Champagne and Thielemann 1991; Jackson and Riddlesperger 1991; Moog 1992; Arrington 1996; Reid 1996; Klein and Baum 2001). This is compounded by the fact that candidates for judicial office are restricted in what they can say by the canons of judicial ethics.6 What does this have to do with campaign spending? The more money raised and spent by a candidate, the more she can get her name out there to the public. Jacobson (1980, 31) found that Although congressional voters have relatively little information about the candidates, both the extent and content of information they do have a decisive effect on how they vote. Normally, incumbents are much better known than their challengers and so win with relative ease. Challengers have a fighting chance only if they are able to use the campaign period to neutralize the incumbent’s informational advantage—which is built up at the public expense over his term of office. Familiarity and name recognition, in addition to political party affiliation, are essential to a successful candidacy (e.g., Abramowitz 1975, 1988; Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1981, 1997; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1984, 1986a; Schotland 1985; Champagne 1986; Thomas 1989; Banaian and Luksetich 1991; Breaux and Gierzynski 1991; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991, 1993; Squire 1992, 1995; Biersack, Hermson, and Wilcox 1993). Increasing visibility costs money, and thus to provide voters with a meaningful choice in judicial elections, candidates must raise and spend money. 6 Although the status of these canons are in doubt after Republican Party v. White (see footnote 5). 26 There is evidence to suggest that campaign spending does indeed increase the knowledge level of the electorate, and thus contributes to competitive elections. Examining elections to the US. House in 1994 and 1996, Coleman and Manna (2000, 783) conclude that: [C]ampaign spending neither decreases political trust, efficacy, or interest in and attention to campaigns. Spending does contribute to knowledge and affect. Accurate perceptions of the incumbent’s record are generally improved by incumbent spending and reduced by challenger spending, in practice typically producing a net result of more accuracy and more competitiveness Further, Alvarez (1997, 204) finds evidence that “uncertainty [about the candidates] generally diminishes across the course of a presidential campaign in response to issue and substantive information.” Thus, contrary to those who bemoan the increased campaign spending in judicial elections, there is some reason to believe that voters benefit from the candidates spending money (if races for the state high court bench are similar to presidential and House elections), and the higher the spending, the higher the benefits to the electorate, and the more the competitive the election. The Role and Importance of Institutional Structures After ignoring institutions for many years, scholars of judicial politics have recently started reexploring the importance of institutional structures to the politics of the judiciary (Hall 1987, 1992, 1995, 2001a, 2001b; Hall and Brace 1989, 1992, 1999; Brace and Hall 1990, 1995, 1997, 2000a, 2000b, 2001). This follows in the tradition of legislative scholars (e.g., Mayhew 1974; Shepsle and Weingast 1987; Rohde 1991; Cox and McCubbins 1993; Hall 1996; Lee and Oppenheimer 1999) as well as those who study the bureaucracy (e.g., Moe 1987; Miller, Hammond, and Kile 1996). The conclusion of 27 these studies is clear: institutional arrangements matter. Institutional structures shape not only the behavior of the actors within the institution, but also the context in which these actors operate. There are good reasons to suspect that institutional structures will affect both the amount of campaign spending as well as electoral competition and the effectiveness of campaign spending. The most basic difference in institutional arrangements among states is the method by which the justices are elected. Other things being equal, candidates should need to raise and spend more money in nonpartisan states compared to partisan states. There are two reasons for this. First, having the party label next to the candidate’s name provides the voter with a crucial piece of information to guide her decision (Klein and Baum 2001; Schaffner, Streb, and Wright 2001). Second, and relatedly, there is the issue of a partisan baseline vote. Since candidates in partisan states can receive votes from voters who vote a straight-party ballot, while those in nonpartisan states cannot, candidates in partisan states have an electoral advantage absent for candidates in nonpartisan states (and thus partisan races should be more competitive). Money should have more of an effect in nonpartisan races, because the lower the amount of information provided to the voter, the more of an effect the campaign (and therefore money) should have. For example, consider a nonincumbent candidate running for the state high court bench in a state with statewide, partisan, single-member district elections (such as Alabama, Arkansas7, New Mexico, North Carolina, and Texas). If the findings from the congressional literature hold, then this challenger can increase her percentage of the vote 7 Arkansas is switching to single-member statewide, nonpartisan elections in 2002. However, since partisan elections were used there for the time period in this study, Arkansas is still classified as a partisan election state. 28 (make the election more competitive) simply by spending more money. The more money the challenger spends, the higher her level of electoral support will be. However, what if the same nonincumbent candidate were running for election in a state with statewide, nonpartisan, single-member district elections (like Georgia, Idaho, Minnesota, Montana, Nevada, North Dakota, Ohio, Oregon, Washington, or Wisconsin)? While not much research has been conducted on nonpartisan elections, existing evidence indicates that campaign spending by a candidate serves to increase her percentage of the vote, for both incumbents-and nonincumbents (Gierzynski, Kleppner, and Lewis 1998). Thus, unlike for partisan elections (where incumbent spending does not matter), incumbent candidates, like nonincumbent candidates, are able to increase their percentage of the vote by spending more money. This suggests that the incumbency advantage (Jacobson 1978, 1981, 1985, 1989, 1997; Dubois 1984, 1986a; Abramowitz 1988; Banks and Kiewiet 1989; Cassie and Breaux 1998; Erikson and Palfrey 1998; but see Squire and Wright 1990) may be larger in nonpartisan states than in partisan states. The effects of money should also be contingent on whether the race is being run statewide or in a district. Other things being equal, there should be more campaign spending and this spending should be more effective (translate more easily into electoral support) in district elections as opposed to statewide elections. While no differences have been found in a similar circumstance between US. Senate elections, which are statewide, and US. House contests, which are run in districts (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1985; Abramowitz 1988), this could be due to the differences in the offices, and not to the electoral constituency. For state supreme court elections, the office is a constant, while the electoral constituency varies. While the total amounts of spending are likely to be 29 lower in district-based elections (Gierzynski 1998), the fact that the district is more compact (both geographically and demographically) should lead to spending being more effective (Dubois 1986a; Hogan and Hamm 1998; Reid 1999). This should also lead to more competition, at least under certain conditions. Hall (2001a) found that district- based elections promote competition in nonpartisan elections, but not in partisan elections. Higher levels of spending, then, may lead to more competition in district-based elections as opposed to statewide elections. The importance of spending also depends on whether the election is for one seat (single-member) or more than one seat (multimember). In multimember races, all candidates run against all other candidates for two or more seats; in single-member races, only one seat is at stake. Competition in multi-member races has been found to be higher than in comparable single-member districts (Cox and Morgenstem 1995). Further, these races tend to be more expensive than single-member district elections (Gierzynski 1998). This is because there are more candidates running in these elections. A candidate will have greater difficulty attaining name recognition if she is running against three other candidates as opposed to only one other candidate, other things being equal. Thus, not only should multi-member races be more expensive, but higher levels of spending should also better promote electoral competition in multimember districts than in single-member districts. Finally, both electoral competition and the effectiveness of campaign spending should vary depending on the term of office at stake. Other things being equal, longer terms should be more competitive than shorter terms (although Hall (2001a) found no such effects), and campaign spending should be more effective in influencing a 30 candidate’s percentage of the vote when longer terms of office await the victor. Further, races involving a longer term of office should also be more expensive. This is because when state supreme courts have longer terms of office, there are fewer opportunities for candidates to attain a seat on the bench. Clearly, the amount of campaign spending, electoral competition, and the effectiveness of campaign spending are all likely to be conditional on institutional arrangements. Thus, failing to take into account institutional factors leads to an incomplete understanding of the political process. This is one of the most compelling reasons to study state supreme courts. While we know much about the dynamics of elections and of campaign spending from both congressional and state legislative scholars, we do not know the extent to which those findings are artifacts of the particular institutional arrangements common to both Congress and state legislatures (Gierzynski 1998). Examining elections to state supreme courts allows for the testing of existing explanations of the electoral process and campaign spending under different institutional arrangements. The Role and Importance of Candidates Campaign spending should affect how well a candidate does in state supreme court elections, because, quite simply, campaign expenditures allow for the provision of information to voters in a low-information setting. It has already been established that state supreme court elections are generally low-information, low-salience elections (Klots 1955; Johnson, Schaefer, and McKnight 1978; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1979, 1984; Griffin and Horan 1979; Schotland 1985; Aspin and Hall 1987, 31 1989; Champagne and Thielemann 1991; Jackson and Riddlesperger 1991; Moog 1992; Arrington 1996; Reid 1996; Klein and Baum 2001). In order to make their candidacies known to the electorate, candidates must spend money. The better known the candidate is, the less money she has to spend. Additionally, the better known a candidate is, the higher her percentage of the vote should be, other things being equal. Most basically, “Money is necessary because campaigns do have an impact on election results, and campaigns cannot be run without it” (Jacobson 1980, 33). Just because candidates are spending money does not necessarily mean that they are spending the money on advertising and other activities publicizing their candidacies.8 In order for money to be effective, it must be spent on those campaign activities that make the electorate aware of the candidate. A recent study of state supreme court elections in eight states9 from 1989-2000 found that only 16.6% of the over $55 million dollars spent was not on activities associated with advertising a candidacy (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002, 10). Further, in 2000, fully 14% of the money raised by candidates for the state high court bench was used to purchase television airtime (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002, 14). It seems safe to conclude that candidates spend most of their campaign funds promoting their election. In addition to the differential effects of spending based on institutional arrangements, characteristics of the candidates also should affect the efficacy of campaign expenditures. There is no reason to expect that campaign spending should benefit incumbents, incumbents who are facing voters for the first time, and non- 8 Other activities candidates spend money on include gifts, contributions to other campaigns, administrative costs, and so forth (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002). 9 The states included in this figure are Alabama, Illinois, Louisiana, Michigan, Montana, North Dakota, Pennsylvania, and Wisconsin. 32 incumbents equally. A predominant finding of the congressional elections literature is that incumbent spending is unrelated to their percentage of the vote, or related in a negative direction, such that the more incumbents spend, the lower their percentage of the vote (Jacobson 1980, 1990; Ansolabehere and Gerber 1994; but see Green and Krasno 1988, 1990; Thomas 1989; Banaian and Luksetich 1991; Levitt 1994). There are three possible reasons for this. First, small shifts in the vote may actually mean the difference between victory and defeat for the incumbent (Green and Krasno 1988). This means that incumbents raise and spend more money the more threatened they are, but since challengers spend more effectively (since they are relatively unknown), it is more difficult for incumbent expenditures to be translated into votes compared to challenger expenditures. Second, incumbents occasionally overestimate the strength of their opponent, because of uncertainty. Sometimes incumbents will wage full scale campaigns even though their opponent is quite weak. A couple of state supreme court races illustrate this nicely. In 1990 in Kentucky, Charles Leibson outspent Henry Triplett $135,041 to $1,500. Leibson won with 72.3% of the vote. In 2000 in Nevada, Nancy Becker spent $180,729 to Gary Backus’ $930. Becker received 60.8% of the vote. It could be argued that Leibson and Becker overestimated the strength of their opponents. Third, and finally, methodological issues such as endogeneity could be obscuring the true value of incumbent spending, an issue I tackle in Chapter 3. While a large majority of congressional incumbents have already won election, this is not true for incumbent state supreme court justices. Some incumbent state supreme court justices are facing the voters for the first time. This occurs because some 33 justices resign their office before the end of their term, and a replacement is appointed to fulfill the remainder of the term of office. Hence, there are candidates who run as incumbents despite the fact that they have never faced the electorate. Indeed, from 1990- 2000, almost 23% of the justices up for reelection initially attained their seats by appointment. Since these incumbents have never faced the voters before, they may not have all of the advantages of incumbents who have previously won elections. If one of the advantages of incumbency is that the incumbent has previously won an election, and thus been endorsed and is known by the electorate (Jacobson 1997), then incumbents who have not yet been elected should experience more electoral competition than their previously elected counterparts as well as spend more money. Further, campaign spending will be more effective for appointed incumbents than it will for previously elected incumbents, since appointed incumbents resemble non-incumbents in the sense that they have not yet been elected. In contrast to incumbent spending, non-incumbent spending has been found to be highly significant and negatively related to how well the incumbent does. That is, the more nonincumbents spend, the better they do (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1985, 1990; Abramowitz 1988, 1989; Green and Krasno 1988; Sorauf 1988, 1992; Squire 1989b; Banaian and Luksetich 1991; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991, 1996; Ansolabehere and Gerber 1994; Thielemann and Wilhite 1995 ; but see Erikson and Palfrey 2000). This is generally because more non-incumbents begin the race in relative obscurity, and as they spend more money, they become better known. This leads to higher levels of campaign spending as well as a higher percentage of the vote. That is, The more information voters have about a candidate, other things being equal, the more likely they are to vote for him. Not that familiarity 34 invariably breeds approbation; awareness does not always carry a positive valence. But it is generally much better for a candidate to be known than to be unknown by voters (Jacobson 1980, 36-37) Since judicial elections occur in a more anonymous setting than congressional elections, non-incumbent candidates for state supreme courts should benefit even more from increased spending. This holds true for both challengers to incumbents and for candidates for open seats. Conclusion Judicial elections are phenomena that remain largely unexplored. Indeed, until recently, much of what is known came from four states (but see Dubois 1980; Bonneau 2001b; Bonneau and Hall 2000, 2001; Hall 2001a, 2001b): California (Schotland 1985; Dubois 1986a, 1986b), Illinois (Nicholson and Nicholson 1994; Aspin 1998), North Carolina (Moog 1992; Arrington 1996; Reid 1996, 1999), and Texas (Schotland 1985; Jackson and Riddlesperger 1991; Champagne 1992; Thielemann 1993; Champagne and Cheek 1996; Hansen 1998; Check and Champagne 2000). While this work has been extremely informative, the findings are limited to those states. Theories of elections and campaign financing have not been systematically tested across all states that elect judges to their high court bench. This chapter highlighted both the institutional differences that exist among the states as well as candidate specific factors that should affect both the amounts and efficacy of campaign spending. It is important to understand the dynamics of state supreme court elections because the stakes are so high. Calls for election reform and eradication are becoming commonplace, calls that are based on untested claims made by 35 opponents of an elected judiciary. Put plainly, we have no idea what forces (specifically campaign spending) promote or inhibit electoral competition in state supreme court elections. Further, we have no idea what explains the amount of campaign spending that occurs in state supreme court elections. The following chapters will explore the effects of institutional arrangements and candidate-specific forces on electoral competition and campaign spending in state supreme court elections. 36 CHAPTER 3 RESEARCH DESIGN, DATA, AND METHOD This dissertation examines all elections to state high courts over a ten-year period and addresses a fundamental question about electoral competition: Does money affect the electoral performance of state supreme court candidates, and do these effects vary across alternative institutional arrangements? Unlike previous studies, my central focus is on the role of campaign spending. Specifically, I examine the effects of campaign spending on electoral competition. The Importance of Comparative Research As discussed quite extensively in Chapter 2, elections for the state high court bench vary on several institutional dimensions. State supreme court races vary in terms of such characteristics as type of ballot, form of electoral constituency, and term of office to name a few. This variation offers a unique opportunity to examine the effects of institutional variation on campaign spending. While institutional differences can complicate matters both theoretically and empirically, it is essential to test theories in a variety of institutional settings. As Przeworski and Teune (1970, 86) state: “All events are unique. But this does not imply that their explanation cannot be based on general theories. Unless uniqueness is seen in a highly literal sense in which every property of an event is in a class by itself, even unique events do not defy theoretical explanation.” This dissertation tests existing knowledge of electoral competition and campaign spending in new environments. If there is no 37 variation in the amount of competition and the effects of campaign spending across institutional settings in fully specified models, then one can conclude that these institutional differences have no effect on either electoral competition or campaign spending. Specifically, we can then conclude that the effects of campaign spending on competition cannot be influenced simply by changing institutional arrangements. If, however, significant differences are found between different institutional structures, ceteris parabis, then the effects of campaign spending on competition can be altered by changing institutional arrangements. The implication of this is that our current understandings of campaign finance would need to be rethought and take into account the role of institutional arrangements in structuring campaign spending. In addition to the difference in institutional structures among elections to the state high court bench, there are also institutional differences between congressional elections and state supreme court elections. These differences may limit the ability of congressional research to speak to state supreme court elections. First, state supreme court elections are generally held statewide, while congressional elections are conducted in districts. Based on the discussion in Chapter 2, this may affect both electoral competition and the influence of money. Second, while the public is generally ignorant of congressional candidates, this ignorance is magnified in state supreme court elections (Klots 1955; Johnson, Schaefer, and McKnight 1978; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Dubois 1979, 1984; Griffin and Horan 1979; Schotland 1985; Aspin and Hall 1987, 1989; Champagne and Thielemann 1991; Jackson and Riddlesperger 1991; Moog 1992; Arrington 1996; Reid 1996; Klein and Baum 2001). Third, and finally, while the term of office for congressional offices is two years, it is minimally six years for state 38 supreme courts. Thus, seats on the state high court bench may be valued more highly by those who seek them than seats in Congress are valued by those candidates. When conducting comparative research, it important that there are enough similarities to make the comparisons meaningful. All of the variation that exists among the states would be meaningless if they made the units of analysis (state supreme court elections) so different from each other that the comparisons would be nonsensical. That is, when conducting comparative analysis, it is important to make sure that the events are comparable. Fortunately, while there are differences between the states that make their examination desirable for the purposes of testing theories of campaign spending, there are also similarities that make this research design appropriate. Here, I examine contested elections to state courts of last resort. Thus, each candidate analyzed in this paper seeks a seat on the state high court bench. Successful candidates will attain a seat on the highest legal authority in their state, and authoritatively decide cases on a variety of legal issues. Most of these elections are competitive. That is, there are at least two candidates for each seat, and each candidate has a non-trivial chance of winning. Additionally, candidates in all of these races have been limited in terms of what they can, and cannot, say (i.e., they are compelled by the canons of judicial ethics to essentially run “issueless” campaigns) (Schotland 2001).1 Thus, these elections are similar enough across states that comparisons between them are not meaningless. ‘ Again, this is likely to change after the recent United States Supreme Court decision in Republican Party v. White (see Chapter 2, footnote 5). 39 Research Design Pooled Cross-Sectional Time Series Design. My research design has observations both across space and over time. Cross-sectional time-series data have repeated observations on fixed units—in this case, the fixed units are the states (Beck and Katz 1995). This pooled cross-sectional time series design has several advantages. As Stimson (1985, 916) wrote: Pooling data gathered across both units and time points can be an extraordinarily robust research design, allowing for the study of causal dynamics across multiple cases, where the potential cause may even appear at different times in different cases. Many of the possible threats to valid inference are specific to either cross-sectional or time-serial design, and many of them can be jointly controlled by incorporating both space and time into the analysis. Cross-sectional studies involve observations over many units at a given period of time. Examples of cross-sectional studies include most research in voting behavior as well as comparative politics. Researchers who utilize cross-sectional designs are interested in covariation, which is “presumed to be produced by unobserved causal processes operating at some time before the data were gathered” (Stimson 1985, 917). In contrast, time series analysts model the causal process in the longitudinal data. Time series designs are common in economics and in studies that use economic data. In these designs, time is theorized to be an important factor in the causal process of the phenomenon of interest. Instead of making the choice between cross-sectional analysis and time-series analysis, I combine both methods of analyses and perform pooled cross-sectional time- series analysis. This research design capitalizes on the strengths on both forms of analysis. Specifically, “The main advantage to combining cross-sections and time series 40 in this manner is to capture variation across different units in space, as well as variation that emerges over time” (Sayrs 1989, 7). While performing pooled cross-sectional time series analysis raises its own methodological issues (which will be addressed as necessary), this design is most appropriate to address the questions posed by this dissertation. Time Period. I look at all contested state supreme court elections from 1990— 2000. This time period was selected for several reasons. First, these are the most recent elections. Hence, the results of this study cannot be criticized for being out-of-date, or not taking into account the changing nature of judicial elections. Second, the nature of judicial elections has changed over this period. These races have experienced a rise in the incidence of contestation over the ten years of this study. In 1990, 60% of state high court races contained more than one candidate, while over 80% of these races in 1996, 1998, and 2000 were challenged. Further, while the average margin of victory has ranged from 58% (1990 and 2000) to 51% (1994), the total spending in these races (in actual dollars) has increased from a low of $364,298 (1990) to a high of $859,518 (1998). This rise in cost has coincided with increased activity by interest groups, who sometimes spend millions of dollars in independent expenditures in support of (or opposition to) candidates (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002). The 1990’s also represent a high point in the criticism of judicial elections, especially as far as the influence of money is concerned (Schotland 2001). Thus, in general, judicial elections were more likely to be less expensive, less contested, and less controversial events at the beginning of the decade than at the end. 41 Sample. I examine all contested elections in states that elect justices on either a partisan or nonpartisan ballot. The reason I limit my sample to contested races is that I am interested in the effects of campaign spending on electoral competition. For uncontested seats, the victor always receives 100% of the vote, regardless of how much money she spends. Further, while candidates who run unopposed may still raise and spend money, the fact that they are not being challenged means that they will raise and spend less (and devote less effort to raising) money than if they were challenged. The 1992 race in Montana is a good example of this. Justice Bill Hunt ran uncontested and spent $12,057. Fellow incumbents Jean Tumage and Karla Gray, running in contested elections, spent $209,304 and $56,658 respectively.2 This suggests that the presence of a challenger affects the amount of money spent by candidates. For these reasons, uncontested races are omitted. Justices who stand for retention are also excluded from this study. While one could argue that justices up for retention are more similar to justices in contested partisan and nonpartisan races than they are to justices running unopposed in these elections (since justices in retention races can lose their bid to retain their seat by not gaining a majority of “yes” votes, while candidates running unopposed have no chance of losing), they are not studied here for a couple of reasons. First, of the sixteen states in which justices stand for retention, eight states (Alaska, Arizona, Colorado, Iowa, Nebraska, South Dakota, Utah, and Wyoming) either do not require campaign finance reports or prohibit campaigning by justices seeking retention altogether. Additionally, in another six states (California, Florida, Kansas, Maryland, Missouri, and Oklahoma), while 2 Tumage spent significantly more than Gray because he was challenged by a sitting justice for the chief justice position. 42 candidates are not prohibited from campaigning and spending money, candidates in these elections filed reports indicating no campaign activity. Thus, there is very little information available on retention races. Further, while retention races are similar to contested partisan and nonpartisan elections in that an incumbent has the potential to lose the election, they are different from contested elections in other important respects. First, the average vote for the winning candidate in retention elections is significantly higher than the average vote for the winning candidate in both partisan and nonpartisan elections. Aspin et al. (2000) report that the mean affirmative vote for retention candidates from 1964-1994 was 74.9%. Further, for the period under examination here (1990-2000), the mean affirmative vote was 69.8%. This is quite high compared to the percentage of the vote received by the winning candidate in both contested partisan (56.7%) and nonpartisan races (55.6%) during this time. Second, and relatedly, very few incumbents lose in retention races. While 27 of 110 (24.6%) incumbents were defeated in contested partisan races and 7 of 105 (6.7%) incumbents were defeated in contested nonpartisan races during this time, only 3 of 177 (1.7%) supreme court justices were defeated in their bids for retention from 1990-2000. Taken together, it is clear that retention elections are significantly different from contested partisan and nonpartisan elections, and hence they are excluded from this study. There are twenty-two states3 that elect their justices on partisan and nonpartisan ballots, and I examine all of them here, with two exceptions. North Dakota, while electing justices on a nonpartisan ballot, does not require candidates to file campaign 3 Texas has two state supreme courts, one that deals exclusively with civil claims (Texas Supreme Court) and one that only hears criminal cases (Texas Court of Criminal Appeals). Both courts are included here. 43 expenditure reports.4 New Mexico is omitted because of data availability issues. In New Mexico, campaign finance records are destroyed five years after the election occurs. This eliminates all records, except for the 1998 and 2000 elections. When I attempted to get the records for the 1998 election, I was told they could not be located. After successive attempts to obtain this data were unsuccessful, I decided to omit New Mexico from the analysis. Fortunately, New Mexico only had one contested election in 1998 and none in 2000. Consequently, its omission should not cause any problems for this analysis. Data In order to specify models of state supreme court elections properly, I collected data on both the characteristics of the elections and of the candidates. I extensively use Hall’s (2000) dataset on state supreme court elections from 1980-1995.5 Using a variety of sources, Hall compiled a database of state supreme court elections from 1980-1995, which consists of all state supreme court races from this time period. This database also contains a variety of state and electoral data, and is the only comprehensive dataset on state supreme court elections. I supplemented the Hall dataset in two ways. First, I assisted in the updating of this data through the year 2000, so the dataset now contains all elections to the state high court bench over a twenty-year period. Second, I collected data on campaign contributions and expenditures for each contested election in the dataset from 1990-2000. These data were obtained by contacting the appropriate office in each state (usually located in the Secretary of State’s office) and purchasing copies of the actual campaign 4 Interestingly, North Dakota does require candidates to file reports detailing their list of contributors and the amount of each contribution. 5 See Hall (20013) for a discussion of this dataset. 44 finance reports. It took over four months for the data to be collected, due to difficulties in tracking it down as well as the labor-intensive nature of photocopying and mailing all of the appropriate records. Fortunately, for elections in most states since 1996, the campaign finance data are available on the intemet, and this facilitated the data collection immensely. The campaign finance reports were coded for total amounts spent by the candidates. While each state has different reporting requirements and different filing periods, they all require candidates to file a final report of all expenditures. Since I am primarily interested in the total spending for each candidate in these elections, the fact that the states have different filing requirements and periods dOes not impede my ability to analyze the data in a systematic fashion. Just as with federal campaign finance reports, candidates for state supreme court must report the total amounts that they (and their campaign committees) have raised and spent. Omitted from these reports are independent campaign expenditures by people and interest groups. As in federal elections, these expenditures may be playing an important role in judicial elections, especially since the amount of independent expenditures in elections for the state high court is increasing with every successive election cycle (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002). Also like federal elections, we have little idea how much is being spent, by whom, and for whom, because there are no disclosure requirements for such expenditures. This is potentially a serious problem. While there is no way in which independent expenditures can be included in the models (because of the lack of disclosure), there is an indirect way its influence can attempt to be taken into account. Media and other reports (i.e., Goldberg, Holman and Sanchez 2002) can be 45 searched systematically to identify those races with a significant amount of independent expenditures. These races can then be excluded, and the models can be estimated with these races omitted. If my results are robust despite the exclusion of races with a lot of independent expenditures, then this is evidence, albeit indirect, that omitting independent expenditures does not bias my results. Method Coefi‘icients. When attempting to assess the influence of campaign spending on the vote, the dependent variable is the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent (incumbent-challenger contests) or the winner (open seat races). The reason why incumbent-challenger contests are analyzed separately from Open seat races is that, as discussed above, there is good reason to expect that money affects these races differently (Sorauf 1988, 1992). This, coupled with the other differences between incumbent- challenger races and open seat contests (such as amounts of campaign spending and level of electoral competition), suggest that separate analysis is appropriate. While the dependent variable is continuous (vote total), models attempting to assess the affects of campaign spending on votes are susceptible to a potential simultaneity problem that can render the ordinary least squares (OLS) results both biased and inconsistent. The argument is as follows: Candidates (challengers in incumbent- challenger contests and any candidate for open seats) thought to have a legitimate shot at winning are likely to attract more contributions than those thought to have little chance at victory. Thus, the better the candidate’s chances, the more money she will receive (and consequently be able to spend). The relationship between challenger spending and their 46 percentage of the vote is potentially reciprocal: money may help win votes, but the expectation that a candidate will receive votes also helps to bring in money. To the extent that this is true (that expected votes influence spending), then using OLS regression will underestimate the effects of spending on votes, since the dependent variable is the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent. The same holds true for incumbents, but in the opposite direction: since the higher their expected vote, the less money incumbents spend, if expected votes influence spending, then the OLS estimates will overestimate the effects of incumbent spending on votes. Jacobson (1980, 1985) and others (Welch 1981; Green and Krasno 1988; Gerber 1998) attempt to account for this problem by estimating two-stage least squares (28LS) models. In order to do this, one needs to identify measurable variables that will affect contributions (and thus expenditures) without independently affecting the vote. This is no simple task. Further, Jacobson (1985, 39) suspects that “no simultaneous equation model of this type can be suitably identified.” Indeed, “After 20 years of research, the appropriate solution remains elusive” (Jacobson 1997, 38). At the state legislative level, Giles and Pritchard (1985) were unable to identify a satisfactory instrumental variable to test for a reciprocal effect, and several congressional studies continue to use OLS despite its potential problems since 2SLS is no less problematic (Squire 1989b; Jacobson 1996). The use of 2SLS is problematic for theoretical reasons as well. In order for there truly to be a reciprocal relationship, the vote at time t must affect the money raised at time t— I . However, this is nonsensical. Rather, as Gierzynski and Breaux (1991, 209) point out, “the expectation of how a candidate will perform affects the amount of money that candidates can raise and subsequently spend.” Thus, the relationship is not 47 Expenditures“ 4:) Votes, but Expectations” => Expenditures“ => Votes, Gierzynski and Breaux (1991) take into account the expectations of the closeness of the race in order to correct for potential endogeneity problems. They argue that expectations of the closeness of the race before the campaign begins are a way to take into account the expected vote. Using state legislative races, they use the previous electoral margin of the incumbent to take into account expectations of competitiveness. That measure, however, is inappropriate for state supreme court elections for a couple of reasons. First, the minimum term of office for state supreme court seats is six years, unlike the two-year term of state legislators. While it is eminently sensible to argue that an election in 1992 is affected by the election in 1990, it is difficult to conceive of how an election in 1996 is affected by an election in 1990, or even earlier. Second, unlike state legislative incumbents, a large proportion of incumbents are facing the electorate for the first time, and thus have no previous electoral margin. Using a measure of prior electoral performance would mean excluding these incumbents, who make up a non-trivial proportion of the bench. Third, and relatedly, using previous vote total also necessitates the exclusion of all races for open seats. In order to take into account expectations of the closeness of the race in state supreme court elections, I use a measure of competitiveness of past state supreme court elections. Specifically, I code for whether there was a close election (decided by 55% of the vote or less) in the last election cycle for the state high court. While far from perfect, 48 this gives an indication Of how competitive state supreme court races have been, and signals to contributors whether a challenger has a potential shot at winning. Another potential measure of the expectations of the closeness of the race is if there was an incumbent defeat in the most recent state supreme court election. The models in Chapters 5 and 6 were also estimated using this measure (coded 1 if an incumbent was defeated in the most recent state supreme court election), and there were no changes in the substantive results. I prefer (and thus use) the prior close race measure as opposed to the recent incumbent defeat measure because I am most interested in electoral competition. In the most recent state high court race, an incumbent could have won with 51% of the vote. While this incumbent was not defeated, the fact that she narrowly won is an indicator of the competitiveness of the race, and may thus affect future state supreme court elections Endogeneity is a statistical problem as well as a theoretical problem. Specifically, we can perform a Hausman test to check if a variable is truly endogenous (Gujarati 1995; Greene 2000; Wooldridge 2002). If the results of this test indicate that there is no gain in model efficiency by performing 2SLS as opposed to OLS, then there is no reason to use 2SLS since OLS performs just as well. Before settling on an estimation technique, the models will be estimated by both ZSLS and OLS, and Hausman tests will be performed. Standard Errors. Still another potential problem involves the OLS standard errors. In order to satisfy the assumptions of OLS, the error processes must be assumed to have the same variance and all of the error terms must be independent of each other. In cross-section time-series models, this is a heroic assumption. While this assumption does not affect the coefficients, it does affect the standard errors. This is important 49 because incorrect standard errors “will lead us to be either too confident or insufficiently confident about whether our findings might merely be statistical artifacts” (Beck and Katz 1995, 636). Because my dataset includes multiple observations from the same state both over time and in a given year, in the strictest sense, observations within states might not be truly independent. To ensure that I am obtaining correct standard errors, I employ Huber/White/Sandwich robust variance estimators, set to recognize the panel structure of the data. These estimators are robust to assumptions about within-group (state) correlation. Selection bias. It is also possible that the models estimated here are subject to a selection bias since I am only analyzing contested races. By only looking at contested races, if the process by which races are contested is ignored, the coefficients of the models I estimate can be biased and the standard errors inefficient (Achen 1986; Breen 1996; Langer 2002). This is because there are factors that determine whether a race is contested at all that are not being modeled. In order to fully understand the effects of money on electoral competition, all races need to be analyzed, not just those that are contested. That is, I need to specify the conditions under which an election is contested before estimating the models on the determinants of campaign spending and the effects of campaign spending on the vote. Fortunately, James Heckman (1979) has developed a two-stage process that takes into account “the nonrandom nature of the observed phenomenon in stage one and removes the resulting biases in stage two” (Langer 2002, 87). In the context here, this process takes into account the nonrandom nature of being challenged for election and thus allows for the unbiased estimation of the effects of campaign spending in state 50 supreme court elections. Thus, I estimate the models using Heckman’s two-stage correction for selection bias. Conclusion This dissertation looks at all states that both have contested judicial elections and require candidates to file campaign finance reports. Looking at twenty states over a ten- year time period allows me to assess the determinants of electoral competition as well as the impact of campaign spending on electoral competition both across states and over time. I employ this research design in order to best test existing knowledge of campaign finance in state supreme court elections. The following chapters empirically examine the determinants of campaign spending as well as effects of campaign spending on electoral competition in state supreme court elections. Specifically, I ask: I. What are the determinants of campaign spending? 2. What factors promote (or discourage) electoral competition? 3. Do the effects of money vary depending on institutional arrangements? Answering these questions will give us a good start into understanding the effects of campaign spending on state supreme court elections. 51 CHAPTER 4 DESCRIBING STATE SUPREME COURT ELECTIONS State supreme court elections possess extraordinary variation both across states and over time, in terms of both electoral competition and campaign spending. As the following tables demonstrate, electoral competition and campaign spending vary based on year, candidate, and type of election. The extent to which this variation can be understood systematically is the subject of subsequent chapters. State Supreme Court Elections Over Time Not surprisingly, state supreme court elections have, on average, become more expensive over the period of this study, as Table 4.1 shows. 52 Table 4.1: Total Average Spending by Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 (number of elections in parentheses) Year All Partisan Nonpartisan Elections Elections Elections 1990 $364,348 (30) $404,937 (18) $303,464 (12) 1992 $576,268 (34) $663,063 (18) $512,373 (16) 1994 $748,398 (31) $1,108,665 (16) $364,113 (15) 1996 $579,336 (34) $722,388 (16) $452,177 (18) 1998 $860,990 (31) $1,147,952 (16) $554,898 (15) 2000 $801,108 (42) $846,465 (19) $763,639 (23) 53 Looking at all contested elections in this period, spending has increased, on average, from 1990-2000. In general, each successive election has been more expensive than the previous election. This holds true for both partisan and nonpartisan elections. One can also see from Table 4.1 that partisan elections, in the aggregate, are always more expensive than nonpartisan elections. Indeed, it was only in 2000 that nonpartisan elections reached the spending levels achieved in partisan elections in 1992. However, while it is too early to tell if this is a trend or just an anomaly, the gap between spending in partisan elections and nonpartisan elections in 2000 was the smallest it has ever been. While Table 4.1 demonstrates that state supreme court elections are becoming more expensive, these spending figures do not factor in inflation. It could be the case that the rise in costs is due in large part to inflation. In Table 4.2, I adjust the spending figures in Table 4.1, and report the spending amounts in 1990 dollars. 54 Table 4.2: Total Average Spending by Year in 1990 dollars, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 (number of elections in parentheses) Year All Partisan Nonpartisan Elections Elections Elections 1990 $364,348 (30) $404,937 (18) $303,464 (12) 1992 $525,809 (34) $571,631 (18) $474,259 (16) 1994 $645,161 (31) $958,840 (16) $310,570 (15) 1996 $472,792 (34) $589,570 (16) $368,989 (18) 1998 $672,148 (31) $896,272 (16) $433,081 (15) 2000 $599,008 (42) $632,022 (19) $571,736 (23) 55 As Table 4.2 demonstrates, while the campaign spending increases are not as dramatic when measured in 1990 dollars, they are still becoming more expensive over the decade of the 1990’s. Candidates for the state high court bench are still spending more money in 2000 than they were in 1990 even when spending is measured in constant dollars. A couple of examples illustrate this pattern nicely. Justice John Comyn won his partisan election to the Texas Supreme Court over Democrat Gene Kelly in 1990, spending $374,659. In his bid for reelection, he spent $864,160 ($705,245 in 1990 dollars) to defeat Democrat Patrice Barron. Justice Deborah Cook defeated J. Ross Haffey in a 1994 nonpartisan election for the state high court bench in Ohio, spending $431,978 ($370,748 in 1990 dollars) in the process. She was reelected in 2000, defeating Timothy Black, and spent $640,817 ($478,473 in 1990 dollars) in her bid to retain her seat. Interestingly, Table 4.2 indicates that the most expensive races, on average, were in 1994 and 1998 (especially in partisan states). One potential reason for this may be the fact that these are mid—term elections. The absence of a presidential party candidate may free up more money for contributors to donate to state high court candidates. It will be interesting to see if this pattern continues in 2002. Table 4.3 looks at campaign expenditures by type of candidate over time. 56 Table 4.3: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 Year Incumbent Challenger Winner of Loser of Open Seat Open Seat 1990 $276,787 $79,073 $294,688 $91,372 1992 $288,903 $239,940 $321,455 $376,686 1994 $474,653 $182,013 $504,750 $382,348 1996 $352,823 $245,619 $263,126 $207,116 1998 $544,891 $253,233 $496,098 $496,911 2000 $476,009 $378,046 $384,716 $321,087 57 As can be seen from Table 4.3, spending by all types of candidates is higher in 2000 than it was in 1990. This holds even if we look at spending in 1990 dollars (not shown). Given what we saw in Table 4.1, it is not surprising that candidates are spending more money at the end of the decade as opposed to the beginning (since elections are more expensive), but this leads to the question of the effects this spending has on competition. Are candidates spending more money in their electoral bids because it increases their percentage of the vote? Or is the spending by state supreme court candidates fruitless, yielding no gain in electoral support? Or does the efficacy of spending vary depending on the type of candidate? These questions will be answered over the next two chapters. This dissertation focuses on the effects of campaign spending on competition. Thus, it is natural to ask: Have races for the state high court bench become more competitive over the period of this study, or simply more expensive? The answer to this question is provided in Table 4.4. 58 Table 4.4: Average Percentage of the Vote by Year, Contested General Elections 1990- 2000 Year All Partisan Nonpartisan Elections Elections Elections 1990 56.64 55.73 58.00 1992 54.83 55.25 54.35 1994 53.11 52.66 53.58 1996 56.08 55.77 56.39 1998 57.87 53.98 62.02 2000 57.93 60.69 55.65 59 While state supreme court races were becoming more competitive from 1990 to 1994, this trend was reversed beginning in 1996, and now the pattern is toward less competitiveness. Indeed, state supreme court elections, on average, were more competitive in 1990 than in 2000. Looking at partisan and nonpartisan elections, no patterns are evident. Partisan elections are, in general, more competitive than nonpartisan elections, but the average percentage of the vote received by the winning candidate was over 60% in the year 2000 for contested elections that occurred in partisan states. Likewise, after having relatively competitive elections from 1990-1996, in 1998 contested nonpartisan elections were won by an average of over 62%. Looking at the examples discussed earlier reinforces these aggregate findings. Recall that in the two races discussed above, the incumbent candidate spent more in her second election than in her first. Does this increased spending yield more or less competition? In Texas, Supreme Court Justice John Comyn, despite spending more money in 1996 than in 1990, saw his percentage of the vote drop from 55.67% to 51.99%. In 1994, Ohio Supreme Court Justice Deborah Cook won with 68.05% of the vote, but she only received 51.88% of the vote in 2000. In her case, higher levels of spending also led to a lower level of electoral support. While these are only two cases, these examples add plausibility to the claim that campaign spending may actually promote competition (or at least does not inhibit it). In Table 4.5, the average percentage of the vote received by incumbents and winners of open seats are displayed. 60 Table 4.5: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and Year, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 Year Incumbent-Challenger Open Seats 1990 56.30 57.23 1992 55.35 53.73 1994 54.32 51.42 1996 54.22 60.02 1998 58.98 55.16 2000 57.99 57.81 ' Average vote for incumbent-challenger contests is the average percentage of the vote for the incumbent; for open seats, it is the average percentage of the vote for the winner. 61 There is no discernible pattern toward more competitive elections in terms of type of election from 1990-2000, confirming what we saw in Table 4.4. While contested elections in 2000 were more expensive than elections in 1990, contested elections in 1990 were more competitive, both for incumbent-challenger contests and races for open seats. Additionally, while 1994 was the most competitive year overall (although 1996 was slightly more competitive for partisan races), Table 4.3 shows that the 1994 election was characterized by large spending discrepancies between incumbents and challengers and the winner and losers of open seats. Thus, while state supreme court races are becoming more expensive, they are not also necessarily becoming more competitive. Partisan versus Nonpartisan Elections In addition to seeing how state supreme court elections vary over time, it is also interesting to see the variations by selection system. The tables above indicate that partisan elections, on average, are more expensive than nonpartisan elections. In Table 4.6, I break down this spending by type of candidate. 62 Table 4.6: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by Method of Selection, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 Selection Incumbent Challenger Winner of Loser of Method Open Seat Open Seat Partisan $524,356 $257,372 $452,075 $381,806 N onpartisan $306,702 $228,624 $279,053 $212,894 63 Incumbents in contested partisan elections spend the most money, according to Table 4.6, while losers of open seats in contested nonpartisan elections spend the least. Incumbents spend the most money, regardless of the type of election. Further, winners outspend losers in both partisan and nonpartisan elections. Table 4.6 also shows that the spending patterns of candidates are the same in contested partisan and nonpartisan elections (incumbents spend more than challengers, winners spend more than losers) even though there is more spending in partisan elections overall. A few examples make this point clear. Alabama Supreme Court Justice Mark Kennedy was challenged by Harold See in 1994. Kennedy outspent See $730,875 to $293,802. In the same election year, Terry Butts and Robert Russell battled for an open seat on the Alabama high court bench. Butts, who won the election, outspent Russell $968,097 to $156,395. In this partisan election state, consistent with the aggregate information seen in Table 4.6, the incumbent outspent the challenger and the winner of an open seat outspent the loser. The state of Washington elects its Supreme Court Justices in nonpartisan elections. In 1998, Justice Barbara Madsen spent $40,687 in her successful bid for reelection, outspending her opponent, Jim Bates, who only spent $24,806. There was also a contest for an open seat on the Court that year, which saw Faith Ireland defeat Jim Foley, outspending him $87,580 to $8,209 in the process. Again, the incumbent spent more than the challenger, and the winner of an open seat outspent the loser. Also note that while this pattern was true for both partisan and nonpartisan elections, partisan elections involved higher levels of spending than the nonpartisan elections, consistent with Table 4.6. 64 In Table 4.7, we can see the average percentage of the vote for each type of election and method of selection. 65 Table 4.7: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and Method of Selection, Contested General Elections 1990—2000 Selection Method Incumbent-Challenger Open Seat Partisan 55.06 56.96 Nonpartisan 57.39 54.27 66 The average percentage of the vote in incumbent-challenger contests is significantly different from the average percentage of the vote in open seat contests for both partisan and nonpartisan elections. Incumbent-challenger contests in partisan elections are almost 2% more competitive than open seat races. Curiously, this is reversed in nonpartisan states, with open seats being over 3% more competitive than incumbent-challenger contests. Indeed, the least competitive elections are incumbent- challenger races in nonpartisan states. Thus, not only is campaign spending conditional on type of election, but electoral competition is as well. Returning to the specific races discussed above, Justice Kennedy defeated See in the incumbent-challenger race in Alabama in 1994 with only 50.30% of the vote. In contrast, in the open seat race, Terry Butts received 53.57% of the vote, defeating Robert Russell. Consistent with the evidence just discussed, the open seat race was less competitive than the incumbent-challenger contest. In the nonpartisan races in Washington in 1998, this was reversed. Faith Ireland won the open seat race over Jim Foley with 68.13% of the vote, while Justice Barbara Madsen won her reelection bid over Jim Bates with only 60.79% of the vote. State-by-State Comparisons The final way in which the campaign spending and competition data will be described is by state. In addition to the variations over time, by type of candidate, and by selection system, the political context of each state in this study affects both spending and electoral competition. Even though two states may select justices in the same manner (i.e., partisan elections), there may be more spending or more competition in one state 67 because of factors unique to the state. For example, consider Louisiana and Illinois, two states that elect their justices by partisan elections in districts. As the following tables will demonstrate, races in Louisiana are both more expensive and more competitive. However, there are also more uncontested races in Louisiana. Thus, while the contested races in Louisiana are more expensive and competitive than those in Illinois, it is also less likely that a race in Louisiana will be contested. This indicates that electoral factors unique to each state also affect campaign spending and competitiveness in state supreme court elections. In Table 4.8, the average spending for each type of candidate is broken down by state. 68 Table 4.8: Average Spending for Each Type of Candidate by State, Contested General Elections 1990-2000 State Incumbent Challenger Winner of Loser of Open Seat Open Seat Partisan Alabama $602,762 $517,456 $1,010,295 $761,620 Arkansas $60,855 $26,214 $244,295 $250,105 Illinois -------------------- $258,276 $248,638 Louisiana $924,472 $650,901 $397,608 $362,205 N. Carolina $202,342 $107,124 $250,924 $56,849 Pennsylvania -------------------- $991,216 $1,121,768 Texas (Civil) $1,008,019 $318,614 $813,726 $483,023 Texas (Crim.) $102,064 $40,523 $67,651 $66,761 W. Virginia $711,193 $180,138 $400,038 $235,295 Nonpartisan Georgia $128,591 $77,334 -------------------- Idaho $129,825 $88,423 $65,057 $99,134 Kentucky $155,457 $392,516 $122,407 $232,758 Michigan $619,722 $442,439 $578,928 $250,025 Minnesota $108,489 $4,381 $57,061 $8,954 Mississippi $267,910 $271,565 $191,461 $71,465 Montana $138,406 $111,384 $291,918 $178,240 Nevada $373,261 $253,787 $427,562 $134,194 Ohio $562,642 $329,791 $391,553 $451,198 Oregon $110,325 $114,194 $159,938 $107,378 Washington $80,329 $46,715 $129,489 $113,689 Wisconsin $367,316 $326,159 $405,349 $461,053 69 Incumbents spend more money than challengers, except in Kentucky, Mississippi and Oregon. However, if only the second-place vote-getter, as opposed to all challengers, is considered, then challengers in Mississippi spend $231,231 and challengers in Kentucky spend $105,197, both lower than the amount spent by incumbents. (Challengers continue to spend more than incumbents in Oregon.) Table 4.8 also reveals that winners generally spend more than losers, although there are notable exceptions (Arkansas, Idaho, Kentucky, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and Wisconsin). If only the second-place vote-getter—the primary loser—is considered, the results remain the same, except for in Wisconsin, where the primary loser spent, on average, $148,960, lower than the amount spent by the incumbent. In terms of highs and lows, incumbents on the Texas Supreme Court spent the most money in their reelection bids, while incumbents in Arkansas spent the least. Challengers for the state supreme court in Louisiana spent the most money in their election attempts, while those in Minnesota spent the least. The Louisiana statistic is interesting, considering candidates there run in districts and not statewide. Perhaps challengers spend this much money because the incumbency advantage in stronger in Louisiana than in other states. Looking at open seats, winners of elections in Alabama spent the most and winners in Minnesota the least. Finally, in terms of the losing candidates in open seat elections, those in Pennsylvania spent the most, and, once again, those in Minnesota spent the least. Clearly, there is much variation in campaign spending by state. A good example of this is the incumbent spending variable. Both the highest amounts of spending (Texas) and the lowest (Arkansas) come from partisan election states. The state in which the 70 election is occurring is an important source of variation, beyond that which can be accounted for by institutional variables, such as selection system. Are there also state-by-state variations in terms of electoral competition? The answer can be found in Table 4.9. 71 Table 4.9: Average Percentage of the Vote by Type of Election and State, Contested General Elections (number of elections in parentheses) 1990-2000 State Incumbent-Challeger Open Seats Partisan Alabama 57.14 (11) 56.39 (6) Arkansas 65.18 (3) 55.41 (3) Illinois ---------- (0) 54.89 (8) Louisiana 47.18 (3) 51.85 (3) North Carolina 49.40 (11) 58.72 (1) Pennsylvania ---------- (0) 52.43 (4) Texas (Civil) 62.14 (17) 56.29 (3) Texas (Criminal) 52.73 (12) 59.12 (8) West Virginia 50.28 (2) 66.91 (4) Nonpartisan Georgia 55.66 (3) ---------- (0) Idaho 49.53 (2) 57.21 (1) Kentucky 50.19 (5) 47.77 (4) Michigan 56.34 (11) 47.21 (3) Minnesota 63.77 (9) 62.32 (1) Mississippi 50.76 (9) 62.08 (2) Montana 57.11 (3) 54.20 (3) Nevada 51.12 (3) 56.62 (3) Ohio 60.30 (11) 57.77 (3) Oregon 61.98 (2) 51.38 (1) Washington 57.27 (10) 55.07 (6) Wisconsin 63.66 (4) 56.94 (2) 72 As Table 4.9 shows, in some states, incumbent-challenger contests are more competitive, while in other states, this label belongs to races for open seats. Further, some partisan states have more competitive incumbent-challenger races (such as Louisiana and North Carolina), while others have more competitive open seat contests (such as Alabama and Arkansas). It is important to remember that only contested races are included, so these data do not speak to whether an incumbent (or other candidate) is likely to be challenged. However, these data do indicate that in competitive elections, incumbents in some states are likely to have quite a battle on their hands. Looking at the highs and lows, the most competitive state for incumbent- challenger contests is Louisiana (which is somewhat surprising since these elections occur in districts, and not statewide), while Arkansas is the least competitive, with incumbents being reelected with 65% of the vote, on average. Open seats in Michigan are the most competitive in that category, while those in West Virginia are not very competitive at all—the winners receive over 2/3 of the vote. This is interesting because both Michigan and West Virginia elect their justices in multi-member districts. Just as with campaign spending, there are interesting variations between states that cannot be accounted for by institutional factors. In sum, the data demonstrate that there is extraordinary variation between states both in campaign spending and electoral competitiveness. Incumbents generally outspend challengers, on average, and winners usually outspend losers. However, there are cases where challengers do outspend incumbents, and where losers outspend winners. Further, in some states incumbent-challenger contests are most likely to be highly competitive, while in others it is the races for open seats. 73 Conclusion State supreme court elections vary tremendously over time, by type of election, and by state. This variation occurs for both campaign spending and competition. Further, in terms of campaign spending, patterns of spending vary depending on the type of candidate. This chapter described the campaign spending of candidates for the state high court bench, as well as electoral competition. In addition to the variation that has occurred over time, I found that both spending and competition varied by institutional arrangements as well as by state. However, what this chapter did not address is what are the determinants of campaign spending. Can the amount of money spent in a race be understood systematically? This question is the focus of the next chapter. 74 CHAPTER 5 EXPLAINING CAMPAIGN SPENDING We have just seen in Chapter 4 the wide variation in campaign spending by type of election, by year, and by state. What explains this variation? Why do some races involve more spending than others? In this chapter, I look at the predictors of campaign spending, and then, in the next two chapters, focus my attention on the effects of campaign spending on state supreme court election outcomes. Specifying the Model Dependent variable. The dependent variable in this analysis is the log of the total amount of money spent in the race by all candidates (Log of Total Spending). Independent variables. Several independent variables are hypothesized to affect the total amount of money spent in elections. They can be grouped into three broad categories: characteristics of the seat, institutional characteristics of the court, and the state and electoral context. Characteristics of the seat: Most fundamentally, whether or not the election is for an open seat should affect the amount of spending (Open Seat). Sorauf (1988) has found that, in state legislative races, open seat races are more expensive than incumbent— challenger contests. In Chapter 4, we saw that in some states open seat races were more expensive, while in others, incumbent-challenger races involved more spending. Other things being equal, however, I hypothesize that open seat races will involve more spending, since both candidates need to spend money in order to become known to the 75 electorate, while this is not the case in incumbent-challenger races (where only the challenger has this difficulty). Further, it may be easier for candidates for open seats to raise (and thus spend) money compared to the difficulties a challenger to an incumbent is likely to encounter (e.g. Jacobson 1980, 1985, 1997; Green and Krasno 1988). Even in incumbent-challenger contests, there should be a difference between incumbents who have previously won election and those who are facing the voters for the first time. These incumbents do not have all of the benefits of incumbency (Jacobson 1997). Incumbents without electoral experience will need to spend more money than those candidates who have already been legitimized by the electorate. Thus, I expect that there will be more spending in races where the incumbent is facing the voters for the first time (Appointed First) than in other races. Campaign spending should also be related to how close the race is expected to be. The closer the race is expected to be, the more money should be spent, other things being equal. Unfortunately, we do not have good measures of expectations of the closeness of the race. However, the actual margin of victory has been found to be a good surrogate for the expected margin of victory. That is, the closer the race is expected to be, the closer it actually is (Jacobson 1980, 1985; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991).1 Thus, the lower the margin of victory (Margin of Victory), the higher the amount of money that should be spent. Partisan control of the court, as for other political offices, is something that is sought after by political parties. Large amounts of money have been spent trying to obtain and retain control of the court (Glaberson 2000a; Dickerson 2001a; Omdorff 2002; ' Indeed, this is the reason given for estimating these kinds of models using ZSLS (see discussion in Chapter 3). 76 Phillips 2002). If partisan control of the court is at stake in the elections (Control of Court), then more money should be spent, other things being equal. Finally, the amount of money spent on one supreme court race is at least partially dependent on how many other races are on the ballot. Money is a finite resource, and the more seats that are on the ballot (Number of Seats), the lower the amount of spending in any one race should be. Institutional characteristics: A basic institutional difference among states that elect their judges is whether the election is partisan or nonpartisan. In Chapter 4, we saw that nonpartisan races, in general, involved less spending than partisan elections. Thus, I expect that partisan races (Partisan) will involve more spending than nonpartisan races. In some states, judges are elected in geographical districts, as opposed to statewide. By definition, these judges have a more geographically compact electoral constituency. This should decrease the cost of a campaign, other things being equal (Gierzynski 1998). Thus, I hypothesize that there will be less spending in elections that are held in districts (District) rather than statewide. Given the differences expected between partisan and nonpartisan states, we would also expect these differences to hold in district elections as well as statewide elections. Thus, consistent with previous studies that have found different dynamics between partisan and nonpartisan district-based elections (Hall 2001a), I include an interactive term taking into account the partisan nature of the district election (DistPart). As with statewide elections, I expect that there will be more spending in partisan district elections than in their nonpartisan counterparts. 77 Another institutional difference among the states is whether the election is for a single-seat or whether candidates run in multi-member districts. Multi-member districts have been found to involve more campaign spending than their single-member counterparts. “In multimember districts candidates will likely be less well known and will be in more competition for voters’ attention than candidates in single-member districts. This means they need to spend more money” (Gierzynski 1998, 25). I expect the same to hold true here: multi-member districts (MultiMember) should involve higher levels of spending than single—member districts. Finally, the term of office for state supreme court office varies among the states. Terms of office range from 6 to 12 years. Seats on the bench in states that have longer terms of office are more valuable than seats in states that have shorter terms, because longer terms of office provide for more job security. Thus, since seats in states with longer terms of office should be more sought after, I expect that there will be more campaign spending when a longer term of office is at stake (Term). State and Electoral Context: The final set of independent variables involves the state and electoral context of the race. First, the size of the voting age population should affect the levels of campaign spending. Simply put, other things being equal, the higher the voting age population (Voting Age Population), the more money that should be spent, since there are more people to reach (Squire 1989b; Gierzynski 1998; Partin 2002). Second, the general competitiveness of state supreme court elections in the state should affect the amount of money spent in a particular election. If there was recently a close election for the state high court bench in a state, candidates may begin raising money earlier and thus have more money to spend for their election. Thus, I expect that 78 if there was a close race (decided by 55% of the vote or less) in the most recent state supreme court election (Prior Close Race), there will be more spending in the current race, other things being equal. Finally, the composition of the docket may affect campaign spending. Some states deal primarily with criminal or governmental cases, while others have a large proportion of their docket occupied by tort cases. The battle over tort reform has pitted trial lawyers against corporations and other business interests. What both sides have in common is their propensity to spend money to put candidates sympathetic to their point of view on the bench (e.g., Glaberson 2000a; Omdorff 2002; Phillips 2002). This can be seen clearly in Table 4.8 looking at the two Texas courts of last resort: The amounts spent in races for the Texas Supreme Court (which only handles civil cases) dwarf significantly the amount of money spent for seats in the Texas Court of Criminal Appeals (which has jurisdiction only over criminal cases). One possible reason for this spending disparity is the differential nature of the dockets (since salary, term of office, staff, and other institutional issues are the same). Thus, I expect that in states with larger proportions of tort cases on their docket, there will be more spending (Tort Docket) than in states where a proportionately smaller percentage of their docket is occupied by tort cases. Finally, I include a dummy variable for the year of the election, minus one year, to control for any temporal effects (1990, 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998). For convenience, Table 5.1 lists all of the variables included in the analysis, along with their exact measurement. 79 Table 5.1: Variable Descriptions for a Model of Campaign Spending in State Supreme Court Elections Variable Variable Description Log of Total Spending Characteristics of the Seat Open Seat Appointed First Margin of Victory Control of Court Number of Seats Institutional Characteristics Partisan District MultiMember Term State and Supreme Court Context Voting Population Prior Close Race Tort Docket Control Variables 1990, 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998 log of total campaign spending by all candidates in the race 1 if the race was for an open seat 0 otherwise 1 if the incumbent was originally appointed to the court 0 otherwise margin of victory (%) for the winner 1 if partisan control of the court is at stake 0 otherwise number of state supreme court races on the ballot 1 if the election was a partisan election 0 otherwise 1 if the election was held in a district 0 otherwise 1 if the election was held in a multimember district 0 otherwise length (in years) of the term of office voting age population of the state/district (10003) 1 if recent judicial election was decided by 55% of the vote or less 0 otherwise proportion of the docket (1995) involving tort cases 1 if election occurred in the designated year 0 otherwise 80 Estimation Technique Since the dependent variable is continuous, ordinary least squares regression is appropriate. I use Huber/White/Sandwich robust standard errors, set to recognize the panel structure of the data. As mentioned in Chapter 3, there is a potential selection bias since I only observe the dependent variable (total campaign expenditures) when the race is contested. Thus, uncontested races are omitted. To the extent that what makes races contested is nonrandom (a likely scenario, see Bonneau and Hall 2001), the estimates I obtain may be biased. Thus, I need to take into account the nonrandom process of races being contested. This can be done by finding some variables that affect the probability of observation (contestation) but not the dependent variable of interest (total campaign spending). In other words, I need to construct a model that predicts whether a state supreme court race will be contested, and thus included in the dataset. The results from this model can then be used to obtain unbiased estimates of the model of total spending (Heckman 1979). Fortunately, this has already been done. Bonneau and Hall (2001) exarrrine the probability that an incumbent will be challenged in state supreme court races from 1988- 1995. The probability of a race being contested was found to be related to the following factors: the incumbent being initially appointed, the ranney index, the number of lawyers in the state, the salary of the justice, the term of office, and whether the race was partisan, district, or partisan and district. Here, I use these variables found to predict contestation in the selection equation to determine whether race was contested. Then, I estimate the model of total campaign spending discussed above, with the selection bias corrected. 81 This procedure provides consistent, asymptotically efficient estimates for all the parameters in the model. The variables included in the selection model and their exact measurement are shown in Table 5.2 82 Table 5.2: Variable Descriptions for the Selection Model of Campaign Spending in State Supreme Court Elections Variable Variable Description Contested Independent Variables Appointed First Ranney Index Lawyers Salary Institutional Characteristics Partisan District DistPart Term 1 if the race was contested (and thus included in the dataset) 0 otherwise 1 if the incumbent was originally appointed to the court 0 otherwise Ranney index of state partisan competition, as calculated and reported by Holbrook and Van Dunk (1993) number of lawyers in each state in 1990 supreme court justice salary in 1995 1 if the election was a partisan election 0 otherwise 1 if the election was held in a district 0 otherwise 1 if the election was held in a partisan district 0 otherwise length (in years) of the term of office 83 The Determinants of Campaign Spending Table 5.3 displays the results for the model of campaign spending estimated using Heckman’s two-step correction for selection bias. These results are essentially the same as the results obtained by OLS regression without the correction for selection bias (as seen in the Appendix, Table Al). 84 Table 5.3: Predicting Campaign Spending Variable Coefficient Robust 2 P > |z| Std. Error Open Seat 0.118 0.125 0.944 0.345 Appointed -0.050 0.187 -O.267 0.790 First Margin of -0.022 0.006 -3.653 0.000 Victory Control of 0.166 0.145 1.146 0.252 Court Number of —0.265 0.103 -2.579 0.010 Seats Partisan -0.737 0.367 -2.006 0.045 District -0.240 0.507 -0.474 0.636 DistPart 0.062 0.643 0.097 0.923 MultiMember -0.267 0.350 -0.762 0.446 Term 0.283 0.075 3.748 0.000 Voting Age 0.000 0.000 0.913 0.361 Population Prior Close 0.217 0.171 1.266 0.205 Race Tort Docket 0.052 0.006 9.347 0.000 1990 -0.727 0.167 -4.360 0.000 1992 -O.386 0.308 -1.255 0.209 1994 -O.306 0.284 -l.075 0.283 1996 -0.442 0.121 -3.666 0.000 1998 0.036 0.155 0.232 0.816 Constant 11.602 0.998 11.620 0.000 Dependent variable: log of total spending in the election Mean of dependent variable: 12.825 Number of observations 2 467 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 202 Log likelihood = 470.35? x2 (8) 28.40 Prob > x2 = 0.000 85 Contrary to what was hypothesized, the total amount of campaign spending is not related to whether the election was for an open seat or was an incumbent-challenger contest. Thus, contrary to the state legislative findings, the type of election is not a significant predictor of campaign spending in state supreme court elections. Further, the type of incumbent also does not matter. Combined, these results suggest we need to look elsewhere to understand the determinants of campaign spending. As expected, the closeness of the race affects spending. The lower the margin of victory for the winner, the more money that is spent. A decrease of 1% in the margin of victory leads to an increase of 0.02% in total spending. Thus, an election that involved total spending of $100,000 with a 5% margin of victory would involve $108,000 if the margin of victory was 1%. Somewhat surprisingly, campaign spending is not related to whether partisan control of the court is at stake. High levels of partisan competition and spending for court seats are apparently independent of whether control of the court is up for grabs. However, as expected, the number of seats on the ballot is a significant predictor of spending. Other things being equal, the fewer the number of seats on the ballot, the more money that will be spent on a race. One fewer state supreme court election on the ballot leads to an increase in total spending of 0.27%. Using the example above, a race with 2 other seats on the ballot that involved total spending of $100,000, would involve spending of $127,000 if there was only one other seat on the ballot. In terms of institutional arrangements, two variables are significant. First, less money is spent on races in partisan statewide races than in the base category, nonpartisan statewide races. This somewhat surprising given the results presented in Chapter 4 (partisan races were, on average, always more expensive than nonpartisan races), but that 86 could have been due to other factors (such as the competitiveness of partisan races). Once other relevant variables have been controlled for, partisan statewide races, on average, are less expensive than their nonpartisan counterparts. Campaign spending is unrelated to whether the election occurred in a district (either partisan or nonpartisan) or was held in a multi-member district. Finally, as hypothesized, the longer the term of office, the more expensive the race. This is likely because the seat is more valuable, and there are fewer opportunities to attain the high court bench. Increasing the term of office by two years leads to an increase in spending of 0.56%. Other things being equal, if $100,000 was spent on a race for a 6—year term, $156,000 would be spent if an 8-year term of office was at stake, $243,360 for a 10-year term, and $379,642 for a 12-year term. In terms of the state electoral and supreme court context, both the size of the voting age population and whether there was a close race in the most recent state supreme court elections were insignificant. However, as expected, the percentage of the docket composed of tort cases was significant. The higher the percentage of the tort cases decided by the court, the more expensive the race was, other things being equal. Specifically, a 1% increase in the proportion of tort cases on the docket leads to a 0.05% increase in total spending. This suggests that candidates are more easily able to raise (and thus spend) money in states where there is a large percentage of tort cases decided, and that contributors are aware that it is important for them to have sympathetic members of the state high court bench ruling on cases that typically involve large sums of money. 87 Conclusion In this chapter, I sought to explain the determinants of campaign spending in state supreme court elections. The evidence indicates that there is more campaign spending when the race is expected to be close, there are fewer seats on the ballot, the race is nonpartisan, the term of office is relatively long, and a higher percentage of the docket is occupied by tort cases. The evidence presented indicates that the amounts of campaign spending in state supreme court elections can be understood systematically, and is a function of characteristics of the seat, institutional characteristics, and the state and electoral context. Now that I have analyzed the predictors of campaign spending, I turn my attention to the effects of campaign spending on electoral competition. Does campaign spending affect electoral competition? Do these effects vary based on institutional arrangements? These questions are the subject of the next two chapters. 88 CHAPT ER 6 THE EFFECTS OF MONEY ON VOTES: N ON-INSTITUTIONAL MODEL In Chapter 4, we saw that the patterns of competition and campaign spending vary over time, by type of election, and by state. In Chapter 5, I analyzed the determinants of campaign spending. However, we have yet to see what difference all of the money spent in state supreme court elections makes. In this chapter, I specify multivariate models in order to explain the variation just discussed. Specifically, looking at general elections for the state high court bench, I address whether money affects electoral outcomes (Chapter 6), and whether the effects of money vary depending on institutional arrangements (Chapter 7). Because of the different dynamics present in elections for open seats (Sorauf 1988, 1992), I analyze these contests separate from incumbent-challenger contests. While the importance of institutional arrangements in structuring both judicial behavior (Hall and Brace 1989, 1992; Brace and Hall 1990, 1995, 1997; Hall 1992, 1995) and judicial elections has been demonstrated convincingly (Hall 2001a), I omit them in this chapter to demonstrate how omitting institutional variables affects the conclusions one reaches about the determinants of competition as well as the role of campaign spending. Just as omitting institutional variables leads to incorrect inferences in models of state supreme court decision-making, by comparing models estimated without institutional variables with models that include these variables, we can see how incorrect inferences about both competition and campaign spending would be made. 89 Specifying the Models Dependent Variables. The dependent variable in the incumbent-challenger models is the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent (Incumbent Vote). In the open seat models, the dependent variable is the percentage of the vote received by the winning candidate (Winner Vote). Independent Variables. The key independent variables of interest in this analysis are the level of spending by the candidates in the election. For incumbent-challenger races, consistent with the congressional and state legislative research, the amount spent by the incumbent (Log of Incumbent Spending) should not positively affect the electoral support of the incumbent (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1990; Ansolabehere and Gerber 1994; but see Green and Krasno 1988, 1990; Thomas 1989; Levitt 1994). However, contrary to the findings about incumbent spending, challenger spending (Log of Challenger Spending) has been found to significantly affect the vote of the incumbent in a negative direction (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1990; Abramowitz 1988, 1989; Squire 1989b; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991, 1996; Sorauf 1992; Ansolabehere and Gerber 1994; Thielemann and Wilhite 1995; but see Erikson and Palfrey 2000). That is, the more money spent by the challenger, the lower the incumbent’s percentage of the vote. I expect the same to hold true here. In terms of open seats, the spending of both candidates should positively impact their electoral support (Log of Winner Spending and Log of Loser Spending). This is because neither candidate has the advantages of incumbency. In order to become better known, candidates need to spend money (Jacobson 1978, 1980, 1990, 1997; McKnight, Schaefer, and Johnson 1978; Becker and Dunwoody 1982; Dubois 1984, 1986a; Green 90 and Krasno 1988, 1990; Squire and Wright 1990; Banaian and Luksetich 1991; Breaux and Gierzynski 1991; Gierzynski and Breaux 1991, 1993, 1996; Squire 1992; Biersack, Hermson, and Wilcox 1993; Thielemann 1993; but see Arrington 1996), and the more they spend, the better they should perform with the electorate.1 While I am primarily interested in the effects of campaign spending on the percentage of the vote received by the candidates, in order to properly specify these models, other factors hypothesized to impact the incumbent’s (or winner’s) percentage of the vote must also be included. These variables fall under two general categories: candidate characteristics and the state and electoral context. Candidate characteristics. In addition to the spending variables, there are three other candidate characteristics that should affect the electoral support of the candidates. First, the quality of the candidates should matter. Regardless of whether a candidate is challenging an incumbent, or running for an open seat, candidates with prior judicial experience should fare better than candidates without such experience (Bonneau and Hall 2000, 2001), just as candidates with prior elected experience perform better than candidates without such experience in legislative races (Jacobson 1980; Green and Krasno 1988; Van Dunk 1997). Other things being equal, I expect that a challenger with prior judicial experience (Quality Challenger) will reduce the incumbent’s percentage of the vote. Likewise, the winner of an open seat having prior judicial experience will increase her percentage of the vote (Quality Winner), while the winner’s percentage of ' Consistent with the congressional literature, I elect to use measures of each candidate’s spending here instead of the difference between candidate spending because the effects of a candidate’s campaign spending depends on which candidate is spending the money. Thus, campaign spending by the challenger may matter while that of the incumbent may not. Or challenger spending may be negatively related to the incumbent’s percentage of the vote (as hypothesized), while incumbent spending is positively related to her level of electoral support. Using a measure of the difference in spending would not allow me to assess the effects of each candidate’s campaign spending on electoral competition. 91 the vote will be decreased if the losing candidate has prior judicial experience (Quality Loser). The political party of the incumbent (or winner) is also important, as it might also influence her level of electoral support. In some states, being affiliated with a particular party (such as the Democratic Party) may help a candidate’s chances of winning election, while in others it will hinder the candidate’s hopes. Thus, I need to devise a measure that takes into account a candidate’s party, conditional on the current partisan climate of the state. There are a few different ways to do this. First, I could use the statewide vote during the last presidential election (or current election if it is occurring in the same year). Thus, for a Democratic candidate running in Arkansas in 1992, this variable would be coded as 1 since the Democratic presidential candidate received a majority of the popular vote in Arkansas. The same would hold true for those Democratic candidates running in 1994, since the last presidential election was in 1992. Second, I could do the same thing, except use the gubernatorial results. Third, and finally, I could use the results from US. Senate races.2 Here, I develop a composite measure that takes into account all of the measures above along with the political party of the justice (Partisan Consonance). This measure takes into account the degree of partisan consonance among the statewide elected officials in the state. If the incumbent justice (or winning candidate), and the winning presidential, gubernatorial, and senatorial candidates are all of the same party, then there 2 Alternatively, I could see if there was any evidence of “coattails” at either the presidential or gubernatorial level. That is, I could examine if state supreme court candidates benefit if a presidential or gubernatorial candidate of their political party wins election on the same ballot. When the measures of coattails were included, however, they failed to achieve statistical significance. Given the high degree of collinearity between the coattail variables and the measure of partisan consonance, both variables cannot be included in the final model. Given the theoretical importance of the partisan consonance measure, the importance of what it measures, and the failure of any coattail effects to achieve significance, 1 opt to include the partisan consonance measure in my final specification. 92 is a high degree of partisan consonance, and competition should be decreased for members of the majority party.3 Likewise, if the justice is of the opposite party of the winning presidential, gubernatorial, and senatorial candidates, then this lack of partisan consonance should lead to more competition.4 Hall (2001b) recently found that older justices are more likely to retire rather than stand for reelection. While older justices are more experienced, the findings by Hall (2001b) suggest that these justices may be electorally vulnerable, and thus choose to retire rather than face the electorate. Older justices may be more likely to be perceived (and characterized) as out-of-touch with the electorate, as well as be perceived as unable to keep up with the workload on the court. Thus, other things being equal, I expect that older justices (Age) will be more likely to experience competitive races. For incumbent-challenger races, as has been discussed earlier, not all incumbents are alike. Incumbents who have previously won election have faced the electorate before and have had their candidacies approved. This is not the case for those who are facing their first election. Thus, incumbents who have not yet faced the electorate (Appointed First) may be more likely to receive less electoral support than their previously elected colleagues, although Hall (2001a) found no evidence of such an effect. Statefi and Electoral Context. Whether the incumbent or winner was challenged in the primary could also affect her percentage of the vote. Other things being equal, if an incumbent (or winner) had to run in a primary as well as a general election, her 3 If the election was held in the same year as the election for the state supreme court election, then I use these results. However, if there is no election for the office in the same year as the state supreme court election, then I use the results from the most recent election. Thus, elections in 1996 use the 1996 presidential results, as do elections in 1998. An alternative way to code this variable is to use the percentage of partisan consonance, as opposed to an ordinal scale. When the percentage measure is used, there are no changes to the substantive results. 93 percentage of the vote in the general election should be lower. This is because having to face a primary challenge is an indication of candidate vulnerability, and vulnerable candidates should receive fewer votes than non-vulnerable candidates. Hence, I include a variable that indicates whether the incumbent or winner was challenged in the primary (Compete). As discussed extensively in Chapter 3, in order to account for the potential endogeneity problems, I need some measure of state supreme court competitiveness. For the reasons discussed earlier, I include a variable indicating whether there was a close state supreme court election (decided by 55% of the vote or less) in the most recent electoral cycle (Prior Close Race). As a measure of state supreme court competitiveness, it is expected that a previous competitive state supreme court race will lead to a lower percentage of the vote for the incumbent (or winner). Whether partisan control of the court is at stake is also likely to affect competitiveness (Control of Court). Specifically, if partisan control of the court is at stake in the election, then the race should be more competitive, as both parties and candidates will attempt to either gain control of the court or solidify their control of the court. Unlike US. House races, the electoral constituencies of state supreme court candidates vary in size. Some candidates run statewide, while others run in districts. Even more fundamentally, some states are bigger than others. That is, spending $1,000 in Alabama is not the same as spending $1,000 in Texas. Thus, in order to control for the size of the electorate, I include a variable measuring the size of the voting age pOpulation 94 (Voting Population), consistent with studies of campaign finance in the US. Senate (Squire 1989b, 1992) and state gubernatorial races (Partin 2002). Like other elected officials, state supreme court justices may be held accountable for issues perceived to be under their control. There has been a significant body of literature demonstrating that the voters make retrospective decisions on incumbent governors and legislators based on the state of the economy (Atkeson and Partin 1995; Lowry, Alt, and Ferree 1995; Niemi, Stanley, and Vogel 1995; Svoboda 1995; Carsey and Wright 1998). Further, the same has been found in both presidential and congressional elections (e. g., Jacobson 1997). Applying this to state high court elections, Hall (2001a) found that incumbent justices performed worse the higher the murder rate in their state was, indicating that these incumbents were held responsible for the state of public safety. Consistent with this, I expect that there will be more competition in incumbent-challenger races the higher the murder rate in the year prior to the election (Murder Rate). Just as the percentage of the high court docket occupied with tort cases affected the total amount of money spent, it also should affect electoral competition. Given the amount of money at stake in these types of cases, both trial lawyers and corporations and defense lawyers will want to ensure the election of judges sympathetic to their cause. Specifically, the higher the percentage of tort cases on the docket (Tort Docket), the more electoral competition there should be. Finally, I include a dummy variable for the year of the election, minus one year, to control for any temporal effects (I 990, 1992, I 994, 1996, I 998). 95 For convenience, Table 6.1 provides a complete list of all of the variables and their exact measurement. 96 Table 6.1: Variable Descriptions for a Model of Electoral Competition in State Supreme Court Elections Variable Variable Description Vote Candidate Characteristics Log of Incumbent Spending Log of Challenger Spending Log of Winner Spending Log of Loser Spending Quality Challenger Quality Winner Quality Loser Partisan Consonance Age Appointed First State and Electoral Context Compete Prior Close Race Control of Court Voting Population Murder Rate Tort Docket Control Variables 1990, 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998 percentage of the vote in the general election for the incumbent (or winner for open seats) log of total campaign spending for the incumbent log of total campaign spending for the chaHenger log of total campaign spending for the winner log of total campaign spending for the loser 1 if incumbent was challenged by a candidate with prior judicial experience 0 otherwise 1 if winner had prior judicial experience 0 otherwise 1 if loser had prior judicial experience 0 otherwise degree of partisan consonance between the incumbent (winner) and the presidential, gubernatorial, and senatorial candidate age of the incumbent 1 if the incumbent was originally appointed to the Court 0 otherwise 1 if the incumbent or winner was challenged in both the primary and general election 0 otherwise 1 if recent judicial election was decided by 55% of the vote or less 0 otherwise 1 if partisan control of the court is at stake 0 otherwise voting age population of the state/district (10005) State murders and nonnegli gent manslaughter per 100,000 population, lagged one year proportion of the docket (1995) involving tort cases 1 if election occurred in the designated year 0 otherwise 97 Specification There are two popular specifications for campaign spending models. First, campaign spending can be modeled linearly, and the amount of spending can be simply entered into the model. However, this assumes that the campaign spending is related to votes in a linear fashion. That is, one additional dollar of spending has the same effect on electoral support, regardless of how much was spent previously. Thus, if a candidate has already spent $100,000, the linear specification assumes that one more dollar of spending will have the same effect on her percentage of the vote than if she had only spent $100. This does not make much sense, as spending should have more of an effect on the percentage of the vote at lower levels of spending than at higher levels of spending. A popular alternate specification is the semi-log model (Welch 1976; Jacobson 1996; Partin 2002). Semi-log models allow for diminishing marginal returns. Thus, these models allow for the fact that spending has differential effects on the level of electoral support depending on how much money was spent previously. There is one major drawback to semi-log specifications. The natural log of zero is undefined. While this is not a major problem in the congressional literature (since very few candidates spend $0), in the state supreme court races examined here, 13 candidates (12 challengers and 1 loser of an open seat) spent no money. In order to account for this, and to avoid dropping these races, I assume that these candidates spent $1. While spending $1 is different than spending $0, this change should not affect the results. Indeed, when the races where a candidate spent $0 are omitted, the same results are obtained. I also estimate the models using the linear specification. The substantive results are identical: the same variables are significant under both specifications. Because the 98 semi-log model allows for diminishing marginal returns, and thus is theoretically more appropriate, I use this specification, although it is important to note that the results are invariant to specification. Estimation Technique Endogeneity problem. As discussed in Chapter 3, models of campaign spending may be susceptible to endogeneity problems. To the extent that one (or more) of the independent variables is endogenous, then the assumptions of ordinary least squares regression (OLS) are violated and the OLS estimates are both biased and inconsistent. In order to correct for this problem, an instrumental variable must be found for the endogenous regressor that is both correlated with the endogenous variable and uncorrelated with the error term. Common practice in congressional elections is to use the incumbent’s prior spending total as an instrument for current incumbent spending (Jacobson 1980, 1985; Green and Krasno 1988), and then estimate the models using two-stage least squares (ZSLS). Thus, incumbent spending in 1976 is used as an instrument for incumbent spending in 1978. However, given that the terms of office for state supreme court justices are a minimum of 6 years, and that almost one quarter of all incumbents are facing voters for the first time, prior incumbent spending is an unsatisfactory instrument for elections to the high court bench. Looking at races for the US. Senate (a much better comparison to state supreme court races in terms of electoral constituency and term of office), Squire (1989b, 1992) simply used OLS regression. This choice is defensible because, in small samples, the ZSLS estimates are also biased (although they remain 99 consistent). Additionally, Partin (2002) used OLS to estimate the effects of spending on the vote total of gubernatorial candidates, and Jacobson (1996) has recently done so for congressional races. Further, as Jacobson has extensively documented (1980, 1985, 1997), the substantive findings about campaign spending hold regardless of whether the models are estimated by OLS or ZSLS. While there are theoretical reasons to suspect that my measure of a prior close race sufficiently alleviates the potential endogeneity problem, endogeneity is a statistical problem as well as a theoretical one. Even if there is no reason to think a variable is endogenous, it may, in fact, be endogenous. In order to test for the endogeneity of incumbent spending, I need to find an appropriate instrumental variable. Unlike congressional elections, not all state supreme court seats are equal. State supreme court seats vary on such things as salary, workload, staff, and term of office, to name a few. Consequently, becoming a member of the court in some states is more desirable than becoming a member of the court in others. The more valuable the seat, the more money one is likely to spend in retaining that seat. Thus, I use a measure of state supreme court professionalism developed by Brace and Hall (2001) as an instrument for incumbent spending. This measure is an index compiled by confirmatory factor analysis that includes that following factors: number of clerks, the difference between justice salary and average employee earnings, the number of authorized supreme court justices per 1000 residents, and the size of the docket. This index is correlated with incumbent spending, but should not independently affect the vote total for the incumbent. Hence, it is an appropriate instrument. 100 In order to test whether 28LS is more efficient than OLS (and thus should be used), a Hausman test must be performed. The Hausman test compares the coefficients from both models (2SLS and OLS) and determines whether the difference in the coefficients is systematic. If the null hypothesis (that the difference between the two models is not systematic) cannot be rejected, then there is no endogeneity problem. In this case, incumbent spending can be said to be exogenous, and the model can be estimated using OLS. Otherwise, 2SLS is to be preferred, using state supreme court professionalism as an instrument for incumbent spending. Performing the Hausman test on the models indicates that there is no gain in efficiency from using ZSLS (these results can be seen in the Appendix, Table A2). Hence, these models will be estimated using OLS regression. Note that thus far the discussion has been centered only on instrumenting incumbent spending. That is, challenger spending (as well as spending by both candidates for open seats) has been assumed to be exogenous. There are some good reasons to suggest that challenger spending is indeed exogenous. First, challengers generally have difficulty raising money, and this difficulty is not likely to change much if their expected percentage of the vote rises (Green and Krasno 1988). Second, recall that in order for challenger expenditures to be endogenous, they must be correlated with the error term (that part of the incumbent’s vote total not captured by the model). However, To the extent that money and its trappings—a large staff, a new computer, a professional campaign manager—inspire additional financial backing, the causal process will be confined to the independent variable (CE) [challenger expenditures] itself. Only fund-raising that is based on information not contained in the independent variables will lead to biased estimates for challenger spending. (Green and Krasno 1988, 904) 101 The story for open seats is a little more difficult. The dependent variable for these races is the vote percentage for the winning candidate. If the expenditures by the winning candidate are endogenous, then this means we will likely overestimate the affects of spending of the vote total of the winner. Likewise, we are likely to underestimate the effects of the spending of the loser. While both candidates for open seats begin the campaign as non-incumbents, it is unknown how easy it is for these candidates to raise money. Given the spending totals seen in Chapter 4, it is possible that as the expected vote total rises, it is easier for the winning candidate to raise more money. To check for this, I used the state supreme court professionalism index as an instrument for winner spending, and performed a Hausman test, which indicates that OLS regression is appropriate (see Appendix, Table A3). In sum, the results of the Hausman tests confirm my theoretical argument that ZSLS is not necessary. For both incumbent-challenger races and open seat contests, I was unable to reject the null hypothesis of no systematic differences in the coefficients. That is, 2SLS is not more efficient than OLS. Thus, because of both theoretical and empirical reasons, I will estimate the models here using OLS regression. Selection bias. In addition to the potential endogeneity problem, there is the recurring issue of the potential selection bias given the nature of the sample. Since the dependent variable (percentage of the vote) is only observed in contested races, if the process by which races are contested is nonrandom (which is likely; see Bonneau and Hall 2001), then omitting uncontested races could bias the coefficients and make the standard errors inefficient (as discussed in detail in Chapters 3 and 5). 102 To correct for the possible selection bias, the models are estimated using Heckman’s two-step correction procedure. Just as I did in Chapter 5, I use Bonneau and Hall’s (2001) model predicting supreme court contestation to model the process by which a supreme court races will be contested.5 The OLS results, without correcting for selection bias, are presented in the Appendix (T ables A.4-A.7). As one can see by comparing the tables, the same results generally obtain. The Role of Money in State Supreme Court Elections Table 6.2 shows the 015 results from the multivariate model of incumbent- challenger contests. 5 The variables included in the selection model can be found in Table 5.2. 103 Table 6.2: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Incum. 0.159 0.943 0.169 0.866 Spending Log of Chall. -l.357 0.464 -2.926 0.003 Spending Quality Chall. -4.606 2.217 -2.078 0.038 Partisan 0.394 0.999 0.395 0.693 Consonance Age 0007 0.002 -3.347 0.001 Appointed -2.933 1.388 -2.112 0.035 First Compete -0.549 1.1 17 -0.492 0.623 Prior Close -3.730 1.603 -2.327 0.020 Race Control of 0.446 1.346 0.331 0.740 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 2.609 0.009 Population Murder Rate 0.148 0.243 0.609 0.542 Tort Docket 0.111 0.075 1.485 0.138 1990 -3.527 1.486 -2.373 0.018 1992 -3.765 2.076 -1.814 0.070 1994 -2.727 2.601 -1.049 0.294 1996 -3.825 2.959 -1.292 0.196 1998 3.889 2.212 1.758 0.079 Constant 64.145 9.007 7.122 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 127 Log likelihood = -624.354 x2 = 13.25 Prob > x2 = 0.039 104 Most relevant for the purposes here is the performance of the two spending variables. While the amount of money spent by the incumbent does not affect her percentage of the vote, the amount spent by the challenger does lead to a decrease in the percentage of the vote for the incumbent. This is as expected and is consistent with the existing congressional and state legislative literature. Challengers can increase their electoral support simply by spending more money. Specifically, a 1% increase in spending by challenger decreases the incumbent’s percentage of the vote by 0.014%. In order to raise her level of electoral support 0.1%, a challenger would have to increase her spending by 7%. If a challenger spent $100,000, she would need to spend $107,000 to raise her percentage of the vote by 0.1%. This suggests that more spending, at least by challengers, serves to promote competition. The presence of a challenger with prior judicial experience also decreases the incumbent’s percentage of the vote by over 4.5%. Thus, while campaign spending matters, so does prior judicial experience. The results also show that the age of the incumbent leads to more competitive elections, being initially appointed decreases the incumbent’s electoral support by almost 3%, and that a prior close judicial race decreases the incumbent’s percentage of the vote by almost 4%. Interestingly, neither partisan consonance nor partisan control of the court seems to affect competition, indicating that state supreme court elections may be insulated to some degree from the politics of the state. The size of the voting age population is significant, indicating that the larger the size of the voting age population, the less competitive the race. This is not surprising, given that the larger the electoral constituency, the more money that a challenger would have to spend to effectively reach the electorate. Given the difficulties challengers have 105 in raising money (Green and Krasno 1988), it is easy to see how they would fare more poorly, other things being equal, in larger constituencies. Contrary to the results of Hall (2001a), the murder rate does not appear to be related to electoral competition. Incumbents do not appear to be held accountable for issues of public safety in these elections. Finally, the percentage of the docket devoted to tort cases is also insignificant. Contrary to expectations, elections for seats where the winner will spend a substantial portion of her time deciding tort cases are not more competitive than seats where the winner will spend significant amounts of time deciding other types of cases. The story for open seats is somewhat different, as seen in Table 6.3. 106 Table 6.3: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Winner 1.033 1.032 1.002 0.317 Spending Log of Loser -1.708 0.479 -3.564 0.000 Spending Quality 2.290 1.753 1.306 0.192 Winner Quality Loser -0.848 2.825 -0.300 0.764 Partisan -0.205 0.850 -0.241 0.810 Consonance Compete -4.762 2.803 -1.699 0.089 Prior Close 2.444 3.768 0.649 0.517 Race Control of 0.226 1.802 0.125 0.900 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 0.850 0.395 Population Tort Docket -0.047 0.103 -0.460 0.646 1990 2.817 4.201 0.671 0.502 1992 0.662 2.853 0.232 0.817 1994 0.663 1.818 0.365 0.715 1996 4.007 3.889 1.030 0.303 1998 -2.816 4.618 -0.610 0.542 Constant 59.284 18.470 3.210 0.001 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 Number of observations = 328 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 63 Log likelihood = —333.284 x2 = 3.71 Prob > x2 = 0.716 107 The amount of money spent by the winner fails to achieve significance. However, the amount spent by the loser is statistically significant and in the hypothesized direction. This suggests that the amount of money spent by the loser leads to a decrease in the winning candidate’s percentage of the vote (and thus promotes competition). A 1% increase in campaign spending by the loser leads to a decrease of 0.017% in the winner’s percentage of the vote. In order to raise her percentage of the vote by 0.1%, a challenger would need to increase her spending by 5.8%. Thus, if she had spent $100,000, then she would need to spend $105,800 to increase her level of support by 0.1%. The lack of significance for the spending by the winner is somewhat puzzling: why should campaign spending not affect the electoral support of winners? The most likely explanation is that both candidates in open seats begin the campaign on relatively equal footing. They both spend money to gain recognition, and spending increases each candidate’s visibility equally. Thus, each additional dollar spent by the winner leads to an increase in her percentage of the vote, but each additional dollar spent by the loser leads to a decrease in the winner’s percentage of the vote. If spending by the losing candidate costs the winner more votes than spending by the winning candidate gains her votes (which appears to be the case here), then campaign spending by the winner will appear to have no effect on how well she does, while campaign spending by her opponent will be significant. Somewhat surprisingly, the prior judicial experience of the candidates does not matter in open seat races. Neither the quality of the winner nor of the loser significantly affects her percentage of the vote, nor does anything else, with the exception of competition in the primary. Having a competitive primary costs the winning candidate 108 almost 5% of the vote, other things being equal, although this result is only marginally significant and should be treated cautiously. These results confirm the need to analyze incumbent-challenger races separately from open seat races. In addition to the theoretical differences between these two types of races, Tables 6.2 and 6.3 show how these races are empirically different as well. The Role of Independent Expenditures In Chapter 3, I discussed the problem of independent expenditures, and how failure to include the amount of money spent by independent groups could affect the results. In order to attempt to take this into account, I identified state supreme court elections that were singled out by the media as involving large amounts of independent expenditures (Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002). Thus, I estimate the models above omitting the following races, based on the Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez (2002) study: 2000 Alabama, 2000 Michigan, 2000 Mississippi, and 2000 Ohio. The results with these races omitted are shown in Tables 6.4 and 6.5. 109 Table 6.4: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Incum. 0.110 1.023 0.107 0.915 Spendirg Log of Chall. -1.206 0.469 -2.569 0.010 Spending Quality Chall. -5.332 2.075 -2.569 0.010 Partisan 0.117 1.088 0.108 0.914 Consonance Age -0.006 0.002 -3. 138 0.002 Appointed -3.483 1.596 -2. 183 0.029 First Compete -0.595 1.212 -0.491 0.623 Prior Close -4.876 2.112 -2.308 0.021 Race Control of 0.909 1.841 0.494 0.621 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 2.321 0.020 Population Murder Rate 0.260 0.31 1 0.838 0.402 Tort Docket 0.085 0.089 0.962 0.336 1990 -5.554 2.720 -2.042 0.041 1992 -5.109 3.266 -1.564 0.118 1994 -4.411 3.351 -1.316 0.188 1996 -5.341 3.481 -1.534 0.125 1998 2.517 3.042 0.827 0.408 Constant 65.356 10.299 6.346 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 380 Censored observations 2 265 Uncensored observations = 115 Log likelihood = -573.505 x2 = 27.90 Prob > x2 = 0.000 110 Table 6.5: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Winner 0.936 1.131 0.827 0.408 Spending Log of Loser -1.761 0.480 -3.672 0.000 Spending Quality 2.122 1.826 1.162 0.245 Winner Quality Loser -0.794 2.637 —0.301 0.763 Partisan -0.559 0.815 -0.686 0.492 Consonance Compete -4.948 2.395 -2.067 0.039 Prior Close 2.828 4.833 0.585 0.558 Race Control of 0.263 2.061 0.128 0.899 Court Voting 0.000 0.001 0.219 0.827 Population Tort Docket -0.061 0.093 -0.651 0.515 1990 2.883 4.998 0.577 0.564 1992 1.323 3.087 0.429 0.668 1994 1.405 2.469 0.569 0.569 1996 4.274 5.178 0.825 0.409 1998 -2.848 5.939 -0.480 0.632 Constant 64.961 18.552 3.502 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 Number of observations = 326 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 61 Log likelihood = -315.489 x2 3.55 Prob > x2 = 0.615 111 As can be seen from Tables 6.4 and 6.5, omitting those races that contained a lot of independent expenditures does not change the substantive conclusions at all. Campaign spending by the challenger still increases her percentage of the vote; campaign spending by the loser of an open seat contest still increases her percentage of the vote. Additionally, all of the other variables retain their significance (or insignificance). This provides evidence, albeit indirect, that independent expenditures are not affecting the results. Conclusion Consistent with the congressional elections literature, campaign spending by the challenger serves to decrease the percentage of the vote of the incumbent, while incumbents are not able to increase their electoral support by increasing their spending. For open seats, the percentage of the vote of the winner is decreased by campaign spending by the loser, but her own spending has no effect on her electoral support. These results hold despite alternative specifications and taking into account the potential effects of selection bias. This suggests that campaign spending by some types of candidates can promote electoral competition. Of course, noticeably missing from these models are institutional variables. The models estimated and discussed here treat all state supreme court elections as alike, regardless of their partisan nature, electoral constituency, and term of office. Doing so yields results similar to those of congressional and state legislative elections. However, given both the theoretical importance of institutional arrangements, as well as the differential levels of spending and competition witnessed in Chapter 4, omitting these 112 variables leaves us with an incomplete understanding of state high court elections. I address this deficiency in Chapter 7. 113 CHAPTER 7 THE EFFECTS OF MONEY ON VOTES: INSTITUTIONAL MODEL The evidence thus far provides some limited support for the claim that campaign spending can increase electoral competition. Spending by both challengers and the losers of open seats leads to more competitive elections. This is consistent with the congressional and state legislative literature. Further, this central result is invariant to model specification. Yet, to stop here would be to paint an incomplete picture. The analysis in Chapter 6 treated all state supreme court elections the same. However, one of the most distinguishing characteristics of elections for state high court is that they vary on fundamental institutional characteristics such as type of ballot on which they are elected, electoral constituency, and term of office. In this chapter, I explore the role these institutional differences have on both electoral competition and the effects of campaign spending on how well candidates perform with the electorate. Institutional Variables The most fundamental institutional difference is the type of election. As has been noted earlier, some states elect their state supreme court justices on partisan ballots, while others do so on nonpartisan ballots. The only difference between these two types of elections is that the political party affiliation of the candidate is listed on partisan ballots and omitted on nonpartisan ballots. However, this difference can be significant. As we 114 have seen in Chapter 4, partisan elections are both more expensive and more competitive than nonpartisan elections, in the aggregate. There are two different methods to take into account the partisan nature of the election. First, I could include a dummy variable in each model (incumbent-challenger and open seats) to denote the type of election. If this variable is significant, then we can conclude that the type of election has a significant effect on the vote total. Further, by interacting campaign spending with type of election, we can ascertain if the influence of campaign spending also varies by type of election. A second possibility is to estimate partisan and nonpartisan elections separately. In addition to possessing the same characteristics as including a dummy variable, estimating these models separately allows one to assess the difference in the determinants of electoral competition as well as the differences in campaign spending between these types of races. Given the differences in competitiveness and campaign spending described in Chapter 4, as well as the results by Hall (2001a), there are good reasons to suspect that there may be differences in both the determinants of electoral competition and the efficacy of campaign spending between partisan and nonpartisan elections. However, before estimating the models separately, one can test to see if the models are structurally different using the Chow test (Gujarati 1995). This procedure tests the entire set of parameters between two data sets—in this case, partisan and nonpartisan elections (Kennedy 1998). Both the partisan and nonpartisan models were estimated separately, as was a model that combined both types of elections. As the results from the Chow test indicate (Appendix, Table A8), there is no statistical difference between the partisan and nonpartisan models. Consequently, I do not estimate 115 the models separately, and instead insert a dummy variable (Partisan) to take into account the nature of the race. Besides the type of election, there are three other institutional variables that should affect both competition and campaign spending. As discussed earlier, not all supreme court candidates run in statewide elections. In Illinois, Kentucky, Louisiana, and Mississippi, candidates run in districts. Hall (2001a) found that candidates running nonpartisan district elections received over 18% less of the vote (although this result did not hold in partisan elections), suggesting that district elections may have different effects on competition in different selection systems.1 This may also affect the influence of campaign spending on electoral competition. Specifically, campaign spending should be more effective in district-based elections compared to statewide elections (Dubois 1986a; Hogan and Ham 1998; Reid 1999). Thus, I include a dummy variable to take into account the electoral constituency of the election (District). The presence of a multi-member race should also affect electoral competition. Competition in multi-member districts has been found to be higher than in comparable single-member districts (Cox and Morgenstem 1995). Thus, I include a dummy variable to control for these situations (MultiMember). A word is in order about how vote totals and campaign spending are adjusted to account for multi-member districts. I adjust the percentage of the vote received using the method first used by Jewell (1982): I divide each candidate’s percentage of the vote by the total number of votes in the district, and then multiply this result by the total number of seats in the district. This procedure has generally been recognized by state politics scholars (Tucker and Weber 1987; Weber, I This was not found when an interaction term for district, partisan elections was included here. For this reason, along with the nature of the interaction terms to be included in the following sections, I do not include an interaction term for district, partisan elections in the analysis. 116 Tucker, and Brace 1991; Hall 2001a) as producing vote totals equivalent to the electoral support for candidates in single-member districts (Hall 2001a). For campaign spending totals, I perform a procedure suggested by Moncrief (2001). I define the “challenger” as the last person to get elected. Here, since there are always only two seats at stake in state supreme court multi-member elections, the person with the second highest vote percentage is the key opponent because this person’s percentage of the vote is the minimum amount necessary to win election. Thus, for the highest vote-getter, the 2nd highest vote-getter is the “challenger.” For the second highest vote-getter, the “challenger” is the person who finished third, since this is the candidate the second highest vote-getter had to beat. This procedure best approximates the amount of money spent by a “challenger.”2 Finally, the term of office may affect the incumbent’s (or winner’s) percentage of the vote. Longer terms should be more attractive to candidates since there is increased job security (Bonneau and Hall 2001). Thus, there should be more competition for seats that have longer terms of office associated with them. To the extent that there is greater competition, the election should be closer. I expect that the longer the term of office (Term), the lower the incumbent’s (or winner’s) percentage of the vote will be. In addition to these variables, the models estimated here contain the same variables used to estimate the models in Chapter 6 (see Table 6.1 for these variables and their measurement). For convenience, Table 7.1 provides a list of the institutional variables and their exact measurement. 2 Since multi-member races are different from single-member races, and because my measures of percentage of the vote received and campaign spending are approximations, I also estimated the models omitting multi-member races. There was no change in the substantive conclusions. 117 Tal Ste Table 7.1: Additional Variable Descriptions for a Model of Electoral Competition in State Supreme Court Elections Variable Variable Description Vote = percentage of the vote in the general election for the incumbent (or winner for open seats) Institutional Factors Partisan = 1 if the election was held in a partisan state 0 otherwise District = 1 if the election was held in a district 0 otherwise MultiMember = 1 if the election is in a multimember district 0 otherwise Term = length (in years) of the term of office 118 Esl Estimation Technique Endogeneity. The potential endogeneity problem that existed in Chapter 6 is also present for the models estimated here. In order to check for endogeneity, I used the state supreme court professionalism index discussed in Chapter 6 as an instrument for incumbent and winner spending, and performed a Hausman test. The results of the Hausman tests (presented in the Appendix, Tables A9 and A.10) indicate that OLS regression is appropriate for both incumbent-challenger races and open seat contests, and thus this technique is used to estimate the models here. Selection bias. Also present is the potential selection bias since only contested races are analyzed. As in Chapters 5 and 6, I model the process by which state supreme court races are contested using the model developed by Bonneau and Hall (2001). While I present and discuss the results from the Heckman procedure, the results from the OLS regression are presented in the Appendix (Table All). The Role of Money and Institutions in State Supreme Court Elections Table 7.2 shows the OLS results from the multivariate model of incumbent- challenger contests. 119 Table 7.2: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests Variable Coefficient Robust Std. z P > |z| Error Log of Incum. -0. 178 0.891 -0.200 0.841 Spending Log of Chall. -1.515 0.494 -3.065 0.002 Spending Quality Chall. -3.867 2.156 -l.794 0.073 Partisan -0.380 1.019 -0.373 0.709 Consonance Age 0006 0.002 -3.014 0.003 Appointed -3.294 1.090 -3 .022 0.003 First Compete 1.637 1.024 1.599 0.110 Prior Close -4.638 1.437 -3.227 0.001 Race Control of 0.387 1.685 0.230 0.818 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 2.068 0.039 Population Murder Rate 0.342 0.308 1.11 1 0.267 Tort Docket 0.169 0.057 2.937 0.003 Partisan -4.425 2.486 -1.780 0.075 District 6575 3.058 -2. 150 0.032 MultiMember -0.274 2.734 -0.100 0.920 Term 2.879 0.785 3.668 0.000 1990 -4.428 1.813 -2.443 0.015 1992 -4.546 2.189 -2.077 0.038 1994 -3.035 2.869 -1.058 0.290 1996 -3.650 3.072 -1.188 0.235 1998 4.061 2.135 1.902 0.057 Constant 55.532 8.933 6.216 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 127 Log likelihood = -618.488 x2 (6) = 19.28 Prob > x2 = 0.004 120 The results for incumbent-challenger contests with the institutional variables included generally echo those obtained for all incumbent-challenger omitting such variables (Table 6.2). Campaign spending by the challenger has a significant negative effect on the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent; the more the challenger spends, the better she does (and the worse the incumbent does). For every 1% increase in challenger spending, the percentage of vote received by the incumbent will decrease by over 0.015%. To increase her level of electoral support by 0.1%, the challenger must spent an additional 6.7%. If she has already spent $100,000, then she will need to spend $106,700 to increase her percentage of the vote by 0.1%, other things being equal. Additionally, incumbent spending remains insignificant. The challenger also performs almost 4% better if she has prior judicial experience, and over 3% better if the incumbent was initially appointed. Further, the older an incumbent gets, the worse she performs with the electorate. A prior competitive race also leads to more competition suggesting that past state supreme court elections affect current races. Specifically, if there was a competitive race in the most recent state supreme court election, an incumbent will receive 4.6% less of the vote, other things being equal. Electoral competition is unrelated to whether the incumbent faced primary competition, and if partisan control of the court is at stake. Also of note is the fact that partisan consonance is insignificant. This suggests that incumbent-challenger races for the state high court bench are somewhat insulated from the general political climate of the state. However, these races are not insulated from the type of work performed on the court. The higher the proportion of the docket occupied by tort cases, the better the incumbent does. This is contrary to what was hypothesized. A likely reason for this is 121 that the relevant interests (trial lawyers or corporations) devote significant resources to protecting incumbents sympathetic to their cause. While they also may support challengers, they first want to take care of the justices already on the bench. If this is the case, then we would expect them to contribute heavily to incumbent’s reelection campaigns, and thus strengthen the incumbency advantage. Thus, while the percentage of the docket occupied by tort cases contributes to the level of campaign spending in the race (Chapter 5), it does not contribute to electoral competition. Indeed, it even discourages it. Three of the four institutional variables attain significance. First, other things being equal, there is more competition in partisan races. Incumbents will receive 4.4% less of the vote in partisan races compared to nonpartisan races, other things being equal. This is not surprising, given that we saw in Chapter 4 how these races were more competitive than nonpartisan races, in general. District incumbent-challenger elections are more competitive than their statewide counterparts. Other things being equal, an incumbent will perform over 6.5% worse in a district-based election as opposed to statewide election.3 Electoral competition is unrelated to whether the election occurred in a multi-member district, but is related to the term of office. Somewhat surprisingly, longer terms of office lead to less electoral competition (incumbents receive a higher percentage of the vote, other things being equal). This may be because 90% of the elections in the dataset are for 6- and 8-year terms of office. Nonetheless, this finding is contrary to expectations. 3 Hall (2001a) found this for nonpartisan district elections but not for partisan district elections. 122 Comparing Tables 6.2 and 7.2 shows the need to include institutional variables in studies of judicial elections. Table 7.3 compares the significance of the coefficients displayed in Tables 6.2 and 7.2. 123 Table 7.3: Comparison of Non-Institutional and Institutional Models of Incumbent- Challenger Contests Variable Table 6.2 Table 7.2 Log of Incumbent Spending NS NS Log of Challenger Spending - - Quality Challenger - - Partisan Consonance NS NS Age — - Appointed First - - Compete NS NS Prior Close Race - - Control of Court NS NS Voting Population + + Murder Rate NS NS Tort Docket NS + Partisan - District — MultiMember NS Term 4- 1990 - NS 1992 - NS 1994 NS NS 1996 NS NS 1998 - NS + significant in a positive direction significant in a negative direction not significant NS 124 Table 7.3 shows quite clearly the erroneous inferences that can be made by omitting institutional variables. While all of the variables that were significant in Table 6.2 remain significant in Table 7.2, the percentage of the docket occupied by tort cases becomes statistically significant in the institutional specification. Additionally, electoral competition is affected by whether the race is partisan, in a district, and for a longer term of office. Table 7 .3 is clear and convincing evidence of the importance of including institutional variables. The results for open seat races are shown in Table 7.4.4 4 I attempted to estimate the Heckman model for the open seat races. However, since there are only 63 races, and given the number of independent variables in the model, I was unable to do so in all cases, especially for the interactive models that follow. Hence, in order to keep the results comparable, I estimate the open seat models using OLS regression and do not correct for the potential selection bias. I did test for selection bias, however, using an alternative procedure. First, I ran the selection model on the open seat races. I then took the estimated probability from this analysis and included it as an independent variable in the OLS regression. If there was selection bias, then this variable will be significant and will also be controlling for the bias. If the variable is insignificant, then there was no bias (Brace 2002). The results from the model indicate that there was no selection bias, and thus I report the results from the OLS analysis. 125 Table 7.4: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats Variable Coefficient Robust t P > It] Std. Error Log of Winner 0.130 1.567 0.083 0.935 Spending Log of Loser -1.928 0.486 -3.969 0.001 Spending Quality 0.679 2.184 0.311 0.760 Winner Qualit)I Loser 1.606 3.450 0.466 0.648 Partisan -0.702 0.998 -0.704 0.492 Consonance Compete -2.778 2.603 -1.067 0.302 Prior Close 5.223 4.705 1.110 0.283 Race Control of -0.022 2.275 -0.009 0.993 Court Voting -0.000 0.001 -0.182 0.858 Population Tort Docket 0.004 0.107 0.034 0.974 Partisan -2.429 2.365 -1.027 0.320 District 0.579 3.074 0.188 0.853 MultiMember 12.584 6.237 2.018 0.061 Term 0041 0.698 -0.059 0.954 1990 2.270 4.894 0.464 0.649 1992 1.239 3.056 0.405 0.691 1994 0.049 3.167 0.015 0.988 1996 2.730 5.539 0.493 0.629 1998 -2.024 4.696 -0.431 0.672 Constant 75.703 17.924 4.223 0.001 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N = 63 F(15, 16) = 30.66 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.3863 Root MSE = 8.997 126 Just as in Table 6.3, the loser spending variable remains significant, indicating that campaign spending by the losers of open seats costs the winner electoral support. For every 1% increase in spending by the losing candidate, the winner’s percentage of the vote decreases by almost 0.02%. A challenger would need to spend an additional 5% to raise her percentage of the vote 0.1%. Additionally, running in a multi-member district increases the percentage of the vote received by the winner. Winners receive over 12.5% more of the vote when they run in multi-member districts. The quality of the candidates, degree of partisan consonance, state supreme court electoral context, presence of primary competition, partisan control of the court, and size of the voting age population are all insignificant. Further, with the exception of multi-member districts discussed above, none of the institutional differences attain significance. Neither the type of election, electoral constituency, or term of office is significantly related to competition for Open seat state supreme court races. In Table 7.5, the results from the non-institutional and the institutional models of open seat races are compared. 127 Table 7.5: Comparison of Non-Institutional and Institutional Models of Open Seat Contests Variable Table 6.3 Table 7.4 Log of Winner Spending NS NS Log of Loser Spending - - Quality Winner NS NS Quality Loser NS NS Partisan Consonance NS NS Comete - NS Prior Close Race NS NS Control of Court NS NS Voting Population NS NS Tort Docket NS NS Partisan NS District NS MultiMember + Term NS 1990 NS NS 1992 NS NS 1994 NS NS 1996 NS NS 1998 NS NS + significant in a positive direction significant in a negative direction not significant NS 128 For the most part, the results are the same between the two models. Loser spending is significant in both models. However, the presence of primary competition, significant in the non-institutional model, loses its significance when institutional variables are included. Additionally, the presence of a multi-member race also affects electoral competition. Thus, as for incumbent-challenger contests, institutional variables need to be included in models of state supreme court elections in order to fully understand the dynamics of these elections. The Role of Money and Institutions in State Supreme Court Elections: Selection System, Electoral Constituency, and Term of Office Now that we have seen how campaign spending affects electoral competition, the next logical inquiry is to ascertain whether the efficacy of campaign spending varies depending on the institutional arrangements of the states. That is, are the effects of campaign spending different in partisan elections versus nonpartisan elections, district versus statewide elections, and single-member versus multi-member elections? Tables 7.6, 7.7, 7.8, and 7.9 show the results of the interactive models for incumbent-challenger races. 129 Table 7.6: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Selection System Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Incum. 0.104 1.386 0.075 0.940 Spending Log of Chall. -0.920 0.368 -2.500 0.012 Spending Log of Incum. -0.327 1.478 -0.221 0.825 Spen. x Part. Log of Chall. -1.253 0.317 -3.952 0.000 Spen. x Part. Quality Chall. -3.465 2.020 -1.715 0.086 Partisan 0.056 1.072 0.052 0.959 Consonance Age 0004 0.001 -3.112 0.002 Appointed -3.288 1.056 -3.113 0.002 First Compete 2.384 1.034 2.306 0.021 Prior Close -4.499 1.484 —3.031 0.002 Race Control of 0.994 1.553 0.640 0.522 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 1.187 0.235 Population Murder Rate 0.206 0.312 0.660 0.509 Tort Docket 0.175 0.056 3.124 0.002 Partisan 13.591 16.686 0.815 0.415 District -6.360 3.172 -2.005 0.045 MultiMember -0.065 2.972 -0.022 0.983 Term 2.467 0.775 3.183 0.001 1990 -2.756 1.984 -1.389 0.165 1992 -3.300 1.938 -1.703 0.089 1994 -1.800 2.918 —0.617 0.537 1996 -2.262 3.036 -0.745 0.456 1998 4.338 2.157 2.011 0.044 Constant 48.360 15.622 3.096 0.002 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 127 Log likelihood = ~612.341 x2 (6) = 15.15 Prob > x2 0.019 130 Table 7.7: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with District Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. z P > |z| Error Log of Incum. —0.202 0.887 -0.227 0.820 Spending Log of Chall. -1.488 0.508 -2.929 0.003 Spending Log of Incum. 1.803 4.498 0.401 0.689 Spen. x Dist. Log of Chall. -1.492 1.611 -0.926 0.355 Spen. x Dist. Quality Chall. -3.753 2.072 -l.811 0.070 Partisan -0.434 1.042 -0.416 0.677 Consonance Age 0006 0.002 -3.062 0.002 Appointed -3.177 0.987 —3.219 0.001 First Compete 1.758 1.097 1.603 0.109 Prior Close —4.847 1.554 -3.118 0.002 Race Control of 0.294 1.656 0.177 0.859 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 2.044 0.041 Population Murder Rate 0.338 0.297 1.139 0.255 Tort Docket 0.164 0.061 2.676 0.007 Partisan -4.450 2.455 -1.812 0.070 District -11.397 39.961 -0.285 0.775 MultiMember 0.076 2.600 0.029 0.977 Term 2.910 0.794 3.666 0.000 1990 -4.940 2.009 -2.459 0.014 1992 -4.754 2.163 -2.198 0.028 1994 -3.330 3.038 -1.096 0.273 1996 -3.878 3.233 -1.200 0.230 1998 3.830 2.266 1.690 0.091 Constant 56.120 9.103 6.165 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 127 Log likelihood = -618.112 x2 (6) 20.44 Prob > x2 0.002 131 Table 7.8: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Multi- Member Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Incum. -0.558 0.933 -0.598 0.550 Spending Log of Chall. -1.469 0.505 -2.909 0.004 Spending Log of Incum. 12.081 6.056 1.995 0.046 Spen. x Mult. Log of Chall. 0.962 5.475 0.176 0.861 Spen. x Mult. Quality Chall. -4.052 2.217 -1.828 0.068 Partisan -0.293 1.073 -0.273 0.785 Consonance Age 0006 0.002 -3.068 0.002 Appointed -3.310 1.085 ~3.051 0.002 First Compete 1.468 1.006 1.460 0. 144 Prior Close -4.487 1.452 -3.090 0.002 Race Control of 0.176 1.703 0.103 0.918 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 2.210 0.027 Population Murder Rate 0.451 0.301 1.495 0.135 Tort Docket 0.194 0.056 3.465 0.001 Partisan -5.481 2.518 -2.177 0.030 District 6385 3.255 -1.961 0.050 MultiMember -165.843 126.471 -1.31 1 0.190 Term 2.742 0.760 3.609 0.000 1990 -4.284 1.959 -2.187 0.029 1992 -4.690 2.294 -2.044 0.041 1994 —3.255 3.006 -l.083 0.279 1996 -3.365 3.126 -1.077 0.282 1998 4.690 2.149 2.183 0.029 Constant 59.344 9.650 6.149 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations 2 265 Uncensored observations = 127 Log likelihood = -617.305 x2 (6) = 26.28 Prob > x2 = 0.000 132 Table 7.9: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Races with Term Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. z P > |z| Error Log of Incum. -6.214 3781 -1.644 0.100 Spending Log of Chall. 7.061 3.720 1.898 0.058 Spending Log of Incum. 1.020 0.566 1.801 0.072 Spen. x Term Log of Chall. -l .421 0.572 -2.484 0.013 Spen. x Term Quality Chall. -3.293 1.975 -1.667 0.095 Partisan -0.583 0.967 -0.603 0.546 Consonance Age -0.006 0.002 -3.180 0.001 Appointed -2.529 1.033 -2.450 0.014 First Compete 2.222 1.066 2.084 0.037 Prior Close -4.535 1.572 -2.884 0.004 Race Control of -0.492 1.482 -0.332 0.740 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 2.301 0.021 Population Murder Rate 0.479 0.317 1.514 0.130 Tort Docket 0.180 0.060 3.021 0.003 Partisan -6.222 2.990 -2.081 0.037 District -7.209 4.027 -1.790 0.073 MultiMember -0.101 2.392 -0.042 0.966 Term 7.285 6.399 1.138 0.255 1990 -5.818 2.121 -2.743 0.006 1992 -5.806 2.348 -2.473 0.013 1994 -4.283 3.042 -1.408 0.159 1996 -4.369 3.162 -1.382 0.167 1998 4.281 2.239 1.912 0.056 Constant 27.884 41.957 0.665 0.506 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 Number of observations = 392 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations 2 127 Log likelihood = -615.045 )6- (6) 21.12 Prob > x2 = 0.002 133 Table 7.6 indicates that campaign spending by the challenger serves to promote electoral competition regardless of whether the race is partisan or nonpartisan. However, it has more of an effect in nonpartisan races. An additional 1% increase in spending by the challenger in nonpartisan elections leads to a decrease of 0.013% in the incumbent’s percentage of the vote; in partisan elections, the same increase in spending corresponds to a 0.009% decrease in the incumbent’s electoral support. To increase her level of electoral support 0.1%, a challenger in a nonpartisan election would need to increase her spending 7.7%, while she would need to raise her level of spending by 11.1% in partisan elections. Table 7.7 indicates the importance of including a multiplicative term that takes into account whether the election occurs in a district or statewide. The results indicate that the results for challenger spending discussed in Table 7.2 only apply to statewide elections. Specifically, a 1% increase in challenger spending corresponds to a 0.014% decrease in the incumbent’s level of electoral support in statewide elections. If a challenger spent $100,000, she would need to spend $107,000 to increase her percentage of the vote 0.1% (a 7% increase in spending). Indeed, campaign spending has no effect on competition in district-based elections, regardless of which candidate is spending the money. This may be because there are other ways for a candidate to publicize her candidacy (such as going door-to-door or meeting people at shopping centers) without spending money, since districts are more geographically compact. In Table 7.8 we see that challenger spending is only effective at promoting competition in single-member districts. An additional 1% of spending by the challenger will cost the incumbent 0.015% of her percentage of the vote. This means the challenger would have to increase her spending by 6.7% to increase her level of electoral support by 134 6.7%. Curiously, incumbent spending serves to decrease competition in multi-member districts, but not in single-member districts. Incumbents running in multi-member districts can increase their percentage of the vote by 0.12% simply by spending an additional 1%. To increase her electoral support by 0.1%, the incumbent only has to spend an additional 0.8%. This seems to indicate that when more than one seat is at stake, incumbents can increase their level of electoral support simply by spending more money. One reason for this might be that since there are several candidates vying for a limited number of seats, incumbents need to spend money to make themselves stand out from the other candidates. Rerninding people which candidate is the incumbent serves to distinguish the incumbent from every other candidate, and thus provides her with an electoral advantage. In Table 7.9, we see the results when campaign spending is interacted with the term of office. Interpreting the effects of term of office on spending is not straightforward. Interpreting interaction terms with interval-level data requires one to determine the partial effect of the variables on the dependent variable (Friedrich 1982; Wooldridge 2000). For example, suppose that the model is Vote total = [30 + fllspending + figterm + [33spending *term + u the partial effect of spending on vote total (holding all other variables constant) would be [3; + B3term. By substituting interesting values of term into the equation, we can ascertain the effects of spending, conditional on the term of Office, on vote total. Then, in order to test for statistical significance, we need to substitute (term — X) *spending for the interaction term, and re-run the regression, where X is the relevant value of term 135 (Wooldridge 2000). In Table 7.10, the effects of different terms of office on campaign spending are displayed. 136 Table 7.10: The Effects of Term Length on Spending, Incumbent-Challenger Contests Term Length Incumbent Spending Challenger Spending 6 -0.095 -1.465*** (0.940) (0.492) 8 1.945 -4.307*** (1.243) (0.492) 10 3.984* -7.149*** (2.185) (2.065) 12 6024* -9.990*** (3.251) (3.194) *** = p < 0.01 ** = p < 0.05 * = p < 0.10 137 The interpretation of these coefficients is as follows: “At a term length of X years, campaign spending by the (incumbent/challenger) has a statistically (significant/insignificant) impact on the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent.” We can see that challenger spending promotes competition regardless of the term of office at stake. Further, the longer the term of office, the greater the impact challenger spending has on promoting electoral competition. For a six-year term, a 1% increase in challenger spending leads to a 0.014% decrease in the incumbent’s percentage of the vote, other things being equal. This same increase in spending leads to a 0.043% decrease for a 8-year term of office, 0.071% for a 10-year term, and 0.099% for a 12-year term of office. Thus, to increase her percentage of the vote by 0.1%, a challenger who has spent $100,000 will need to spend $107,000 for a six-year term, $102,300 for an eight- year term, $101,400 for a ten-year term, and only $101,010 for a twelve—year term. The longer the term, the more effective the campaign spending of the challenger. Incumbent spending seems to be significant only when longer terms of office are at stake, and even then it is only marginally the case. It is also important to note that when one looks at the relative ability of the incumbent to increase her electoral support, it is clear that challenger spending is still more effective. For 8—year terms of office, a 1% increase in incumbent spending increases her percentage of the vote by 0.04%, while the same 1% of additional spending by the challenger decreases the incumbent’s electoral support by 0.071%. Further, since incumbents generally spend more money than challengers (see Chapter 4), an additional 1% of challenger spending is, in general, much less actual spending than an additional 1% of incumbent spending. Taking the average amount of spending for both incumbents and challengers from Chapter 4 (Table 4.8) in 138 the State of Washington illustrates this point nicely. An additional 1% of spending by an incumbent in Washington is $803.29 ($80,329 x 0.01), and this would correspond to a 0.04% increase in her level of electoral support. However, for a challenger to decrease the incumbent’s percentage of the vote by 0.071%, she would only have to spend $467.15 ($46,715 x 0.01). Thus, while incumbent spending in marginally significant when longer terms of office are stake, we should not make too much of this result. Now, we turn to open seat races. Tables 7.11, 7.12, 7.13, and 7.14 display the results from the interactive models. 139 Table 7.11: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Selection System Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. t P > It] Error Log of Winner -3.133 2.344 -1.337 0.200 Spending Log of Loser -1.919 1.236 -1.553 0.140 Spending Log of Winner 4.292 2.645 1.623 0.124 Spen. x Part. Log of Loser -0.237 1.312 -0.181 0.859 Spen. x Part. Quality 0.615 2.402 0.256 0.801 Winner Quality Loser 2.296 3.961 0.580 0.570 Partisan -0.489 1.326 -0.369 0.717 Consonance Compete -3.044 3.433 -0.887 0.388 Prior Close 6.540 4.953 1.320 0.205 Race Control of -0. 109 1.929 -0.057 0.956 Court Voting -0.000 0.001 -0.070 0.945 Population Tort Docket -0.042 0.107 -0.394 0.699 Partisan —53.051 36.251 -1.463 0.163 District 0.797 2.969 0.268 0.792 MultiMember 1 1.009 6.126 1.797 0.091 Term 0.287 0.671 0.427 0.675 1990 1.686 4.766 0.354 0.699 1992 0.301 2.680 0.112 0.912 1994 -0.481 3.377 -0.142 0.889 1996 2.645 5.749 0.460 0.652 1998 -3.191 4.958 -0.644 0.529 Constant 113.793 33.764 3.370 0.004 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N = 63 F (15, 16) = 27.97 Prob > F = 0.0000 R2 = 0.4125 Root MSE = 9.015 140 Table 7.12: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with District Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. t P > It] Error Log of Winner -1.832 1.370 -1.338 0.200 Spending Log of Loser -2.049 0.441 4.646 0.000 Spending Log of Winner 5.713 2.099 2.722 0.015 Spen. x Dist. Log of Loser 3.881 1.364 2.845 0.012 Spen. x Dist. Quality 3 .406 2.122 1.605 0.128 Winner Quality Loser 1.336 3.300 0.405 0.691 Partisan -1.384 1.385 -0.999 0.333 Consonance Compete -2.330 3.300 -0.706 0.490 Prior Close 5.228 4.013 1.303 0.211 Race Control of 2.029 1.904 1.065 0.303 Court Voting -0.000 0.000 -0.418 0.682 Population Tort Docket 0.089 0.088 1.007 0.329 Partisan -1.836 1.855 -0.990 0.337 District -118.139 23.006 -5. 135 0.000 MultiMember 12.451 5.378 2.315 0.034 Term 0.536 0.540 0.993 0.336 1990 4.433 4.043 1.096 0.289 1992 3.927 5.532 0.710 0.488 1994 1.056 3.563 0.297 0.771 1996 0.179 4.727 0.038 0.970 1998 -2.211 4.558 -0.485 0.634 Constant 92.874 12.406 7.486 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N=63 F (15, 16) = 99.79 Prob > F = 0.0000 R2 = 0.5149 Root MSE = 8.192 141 Table 7.13: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Multi-Member Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. t P > M Error Log of Winner 0.994 1.783 0.558 0.585 Spending Log of Loser -1.891 0.530 -3.568 0.003 Spending Log of Winner -15.760 16.446 -0.958 0.352 Spen. x Mult. Log of Loser 6.269 14.434 0.434 0.670 Spen. x Mult. Quality 1.436 2.074 0.692 0.499 Winner Quality Loser 1.014 3.496 0.290 0.776 Partisan -1.027 1.134 —0.905 0.379 Consonance Compete -2.357 2.992 -0.788 0.442 Prior Close 2.967 4.010 0.740 0.470 Race Control of -1.058 2.406 -0.440 0.666 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 0.487 0.633 Population Tort Docket 0.005 0.095 0.050 0.960 Partisan -2.773 2.534 -1.094 0.290 District 2.339 3.398 0.688 0.501 MultiMember 143.083 85.546 1.673 0.114 Term 0349 0.832 -0.419 0.681 1990 2.658 4.927 0.539 0.597 1992 1.553 2.952 0.526 0.606 1994 0.517 3.000 0.172 0.865 1996 4.411 5.304 0.832 0.418 1998 0720 4.383 -0.164 0.872 Constant 66.229 21.500 3 .080 0.007 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N = 63 F (15, 16) = 61.56 Prob > F = 0.0000 R2 = 0.4133 Root MSE = 9.001 142 Table 7.14: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats with Term Interaction Terms Variable Coefficient Robust Std. t P > M Enor Log of Winner -9.233 4.215 -2.191 0.044 Spending Log of Loser -4.449 1.727 -2.577 0.020 Spending Log of Winner 1.201 0.481 2.499 0.024 Spen. x Term Log of Loser 0.410 0.268 1.531 0.145 Spen. x Term Quality 1.753 1.928 0.909 0.377 Winner Quality Loser 1.070 3.569 0.300 0.768 Partisan -0.727 1.089 -0.668 0.514 Consonance Compete -2.891 3.027 -0.955 0.354 Prior Close 6.244 4.197 1.488 0.156 Race Control of 1.657 2.070 0.801 0.435 Court Voting -0.000 0.001 -0.843 0.412 Population Tort Docket 0.080 0.069 1.151 0.266 Partisan -0.748 2.454 -0.305 0.764 District -0.055 2.635 -0.021 0.984 MultiMember 8.131 5.846 1.391 0.183 Term -20.076 5.627 -3.568 0.003 1990 3.326 4.640 0.717 0.484 1992 1.912 3.787 0.505 0.620 1994 0.887 3.356 0.264 0.795 1996 1.795 5.096 0.352 0.729 1998 -4.483 5.198 -0.862 0.401 Constant 220.766 42.966 5.138 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N=63 F (15, 16): 38.38 Prob > F = 0.0000 R2 = 0.4472 Root MSE = 8.745 143 The results for open seats, like those for incumbent-challenger contests, show that institutions can affect the influence of campaign spending on the electoral support of the winner. In Table 7.11, we see that the influence of campaign spending on the outcome of open seat elections is not contingent on selection system. Indeed, campaign spending does not appear to be significant at all (although a likely reason for this is the collinearity introduced by the interaction term; campaign spending by the losing candidate—Table 7.4—likely still matters). Table 7.12 displays the results for district-based elections interactive model. Competition is promoted by campaign spending by the loser in statewide elections. A 1% increase in campaign spending by the loser leads to a 0.02% decrease in the winner’s percentage of the vote, other things being equal. The losing candidate can increase her percentage of the vote by 0.1% if she spends 5% more. However, this effect is reversed in district-based elections. Indeed, campaign spending by either the winner or the loser will serve to decrease electoral competition in district-based elections. A 1% increase in the spending by the winner increases her level of electoral support by 0.057%, while the same increase in spending by the loser increases the winner’s percentage of the vote by 0.039%. This result is contrary with what was found for incumbent-challenger contests: campaign spending by neither the incumbent nor the challenger significantly affected the incumbent’s percentage of the vote, for both partisan and nonpartisan elections). This is further evidence that open seat races are governed by different dynamics than incumbent- challenger contests. In Table 7.13, we see that campaign spending by the loser in single-member districts significantly decreases the electoral support of the winner, and thus promotes 144 competition. Specifically, the winner’s percentage of vote can be reduced by 0.019% if the loser increases her spending by 1%. Likewise, the winner’s percentage of the vote can be reduced by 0.1% if the loser increases her spending by 5.3%. Campaign spending has no affect on competition in multi—member elections. Table 7.14 looks at the term of office. The effects term length has on campaign spending are shown in Table 7.15. 145 Table 7.15: The Effects of Term Length on Spending, Open Seat Races Term Length Winner Spending Loser Spending 6 -2.028 -1.998*** (1.564) (0.388) 8 0.374 -1.168* (1.017) (0.596) 10 2.776*** -0.347 (1.213) (1.064) 12 5.177*** 0.473 (1.938) (1.577) *** = p < 0.01 ** = p < 0.05 * = p < 0.10 146 The results presented in Table 7.15 are interesting. While campaign spending by the losing candidates promotes competition with shorter terms of office (six and eight years), campaign spending by the winner serves to decrease competition when longer terms of office are at stake (ten and twelve years). This could be a result of the electoral dynamics in the state with longer terms of office (Illinois, Louisiana, Pennsylvania, and Wisconsin), or it could be the case that spending retards competition when longer terms of office are at stake (although there is no theoretical reason to think this is the case). Overall, the general lesson from these models is clear: institutions affect how campaign spending can influence electoral support. Some institutional arrangements promote competition (single-member districts) while others retard it. And, under other institutional arrangements (district-based elections, longer terms of office), the effects depend upon the type of race. The Role of Independent Expenditures Tables 7.16 and 7.17 show the results of the models estimated in Tables 7.2 and 7.4, omitting the races that contained large amounts of independent expenditures. 147 Table 7.16: The Effects of Money on Votes, Incumbent-Challenger Contests, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted Variable Coefficient Robust Std. 2 P > |z| Error Log of Incum. -0.191 0.999 —0.191 0.848 Spending Log of Chall. -1.347 0.530 -2.543 0.011 Spending Quality Chall. -4.901 2.045 -2.396 0.017 Partisan -0.437 1.157 -0.377 0.706 Consonance Age -0.006 0.002 -2.817 0.005 Appointed -3.975 1.372 -2.898 0.004 First Compete 1.434 1.080 1.327 0.184 Prior Close -5.551 1.950 -2.847 0.004 Race Control of 0.618 2.135 0.289 0.772 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 2.239 0.017 Population Murder Rate 0.397 0.374 1.061 0.289 Tort Docket 0.144 0.070 2.066 0.039 Partisan -5.564 3.521 -1.580 0.114 District -4.374 4.039 -1.083 0.279 MultiMember -0.986 3.049 -0.323 0.746 Term 3.019 0.886 3.409 0.001 1990 -6.019 2.592 -2.322 0.020 1992 -5.427 3.286 -1.652 0.099 1994 -4.149 3.466 -1.197 0.231 1996 -4.928 3.434 —1.435 0.151 1998 2.887 2.560 1.128 0.259 Constant 55.689 10.593 5.257 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 54.94 Number of observations = 380 Censored observations = 265 Uncensored observations = 115 Log likelihood = -568.652 x2 (6) = 17.34 Prob > x2 = 0.008 148 Table 7.17: The Effects of Money on Votes, Open Seats, with Independent Expenditure Races Omitted Variable Coefficient Robust Std. t P > M Error Log Of Winner 0.119 1.533 0.078 0.939 Spending Log of Loser -1.928 0.490 -3.933 0.001 Spending Quality 0.671 2.226 0.302 0.767 Winner Quality Loser 1.557 3.400 0.458 0.653 Partisan -0.685 1.071 -0.640 0.531 Consonance Compete -2.816 2.684 - 1.049 0.310 Prior Close 5.168 5.274 0.980 0.342 Race Control of -0.057 2.424 -0.024 0.981 Court Voting -0.000 0.001 -0.114 0.910 Population Tort Docket 0.003 0.108 0.024 0.982 Partisan -2.531 3.173 -0.798 0.437 District 0.646 3.452 0.187 0.854 MultiMember 12.571 6.371 1.973 0.066 Term 0021 0.732 -0.028 0.978 1990 2.366 5.264 0.450 0.659 1992 1.286 3.025 0.425 0.676 1994 0.102 3.352 0.030 0.976 1996 2.810 6.078 0.462 0.650 1998 -1.912 5.885 -0.325 0.749 Constant 75.663 18.259 4.144 0.001 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for winner Mean of dependent variable: 55.88 N = 61 F (15, 16) = 37.16 Prob > F = 0.0000 R2 = 0.3864 Root MSE = 9.212 149 Omitting those races that involved a lot of independent expenditures does not affect the efficacy of campaign spending in incumbent-challenger races, as seen in Table 7.16. Campaign spending by the challenger continues to promote electoral competition, while spending by the incumbent remains statistically insignificant. Finally, all of the other variables significant in Table 7.2 are significant in Table 7.16, with two exceptions. In the results for all races, competition was promoted by an election occurring in a district and in a partisan state. These variables are not significant when races involving a large amount of independent expenditures are omitted. This suggests that the results for the district variable in Table 7 .2 are driven by elections in Mississippi (since it is the only state with both district elections and a large amount of independent expenditures), while Alabama is a prime determinant of the significance of the partisan variable achieving significance, since it is the only state with both partisan elections and a large amount of independent expenditures (although the significance of the partisan variable is marginal in Table 7.2). As Table 7.17 shows, excluding those races heavily infused with independent expenditures does not significantly affect the results for open seat races. The spending by the losing candidate continues to promote competition, while the spending by the winning candidate does not affect her percentage of the vote. Further multi-member open seat races contribute to less electoral competition. However, there is one difference: when races with a large amount of independent expenditures are excluded, the fact that there was a close race in the most recent state high court election loses its significance. This suggests that previous close races may be an indication that there will be a large amount of independent expenditures in subsequent races. 150 Overall, consistent with the results obtained in Chapter 6, excluding those elections with a lot of independent expenditures does not significantly affect the conclusions reached about the efficacy of campaign spending. Conclusion This chapter sought to ascertain the affects of institutional variables on competition and on the efficacy of campaign spending. The institutional variation present in state supreme court elections makes them ideal laboratories for studying the effects of institutions on political processes. In sum, one cannot escape the conclusion that institutions matter. Not only do institutional arrangements structure competition (either by promotion or retardation), but they also affect the efficacy of campaign spending. The results suggest that those who lament the lack of competitive races for the state high court bench, or who are concerned with the effects of campaign spending can alleviate their concerns by changing institutional arrangements. More will be said about this in Chapter 8. 151 CHAPT ER 8 CONCLUSION This dissertation has explored the role of campaign spending in promoting (or retarding) electoral competition in state supreme court elections over a ten-year period. The results of the empirical analysis suggest that many factors influence both campaign spending and electoral competition in elections to the state high court bench: characteristics of the candidates, the state and electoral context, campaign spending, and institutional factors. In this chapter, I conclude by tying together the empirical results with the theory developed in Chapters 1 and 2, as well as talk about the implications of these results and directions for future research. Summary of Results This project was one of the first to examine state supreme court elections systematically (but see Dubois 1980; Bonneau 2001b; Hall 2001a). In Chapter 4, we saw that both competition and campaign spending varied by type of selection system, by type of race, by state, and over time. In general, partisan elections were more competitive and more expensive than nonpartisan elections. Incumbent-challenger contests in partisan elections were more competitive than their open seat counterparts, while this was reversed in nonpartisan states. Chapter 5 examined the determinants of total campaign spending for a state supreme court seat. Higher levels of campaign spending were found to be related to the margin of victory for the winning candidate, the number of state supreme court seats on 152 the ballot, whether the election was held in a partisan or nonpartisan state, the length of the term of office, and the percentage of the docket occupied by tort cases. Specifically, the lower the margin of victory, the fewer the number of seats on the ballot, the higher the percentage of the docket occupied by tort cases, and elections held in nonpartisan states and for longer terms of office all lead to higher amounts of campaign spending by the candidates, other things being equal. In Chapter 6, I sought to ascertain the effects campaign spending had on the percentage of the vote received by the incumbent (or, in the case of open seats, the percentage of the vote received by the winner). However, I did not include any of the institutional variables in these models. Hence, these models treated all state supreme court elections the same. The principal reason for doing this was so that there was a baseline model against which the institutional models could be compared. That is, I wanted to estimate the models without institutional variables to better show the effects of institutions when they were included in subsequent models. The central finding of Chapter 6 was that, consistent with the congressional and state legislative literature, challenger spending served to decrease the electoral support of the incumbent, and spending by the losing candidate decreased the winner’s percentage of the vote. That is, competition was promoted by campaign spending by certain candidates. Additionally, competition was promoted in incumbent-challenger races by the presence of a quality challenger, the age of the incumbent, whether the incumbent was initially appointed to the bench, and if there was a prior close state supreme court election. The size of the voting age population served to decrease competition, indicating that the incumbency advantage is magnified in larger states. For open seat elections, in 153 addition to campaign spending by the loser, if the winner was challenged in a primary, she was more likely to receive a lower percentage of the vote, other things being equal. These results hold even if races that involved a lot of independent expenditures are omitted, as well as under different model specifications and estimation techniques. The extent to which this central result held in different institutional circumstances was the subject of Chapter 7. The differences between the non-institutional models of incumbent-challenger contests were displayed in Table 7.3. In addition to the same variables attaining significance that did in the non-institutional models, in the institutional model the percentage of the docket occupied by tort cases decreases electoral competition, while partisan races and district—based elections promote electoral competition. In terms of open seats, in addition to loser spending retaining its significance, multi—member districts tend to discourage competition. Further, there was no difference in campaign spending between partisan and nonpartisan elections. Looking at the effects of institutional variables on the efficacy of campaign spending yielded mixed results. Challenger spending promoted competition in both partisan and nonpartisan races, as well as in statewide races, single-member districts, and for longer terms of office. For open seats, campaign spending by the loser led to more competition in statewide races, as well as elections that occurred in single—member districts. In district-based elections, campaign spending by both the winner and the loser served to decrease competition. Further, challenger spending served to promote competition when shorter terms of office awaited the victor, while incumbent spending served to decrease competition when longer terms of office were at stake, likely for the reasons discussed in Chapter 7. 154 In sum, the results suggest that campaign spending will have the greatest influence in promoting competition in statewide, single-member district elections, regardless of the type of election (partisan or nonpartisan) or whether the election is an incumbent-challenger race or a race for an open seat. Also, for incumbent-challenger races, the longer the term of office at stake, the more effective campaign spending will be in promoting competition. The Importance of Electoral Competition In Chapter 1, I discussed the role of competition in electoral and democratic theory. Electoral competition is important because, by its very nature, it serves as a constraint on the actions of elected officials. Regardless of the level of knowledge or the participation of the electorate, electoral competition brings elected officials in line with the preferences of their constituents (e. g., Squire 1989a). The same holds true for state supreme court justices: electoral competition affects not only judicial behavior in terms of dissent rates, but also affects the outcome of cases (Brace and Hall 1990, 1995, 1997; Hall 1987, 1992, 1995). Thus, electoral competition plays a key role in understanding political life. The link between electoral competition and judicial behavior cannot be understated. Consider three justices sitting on a state supreme court. These justices are similar in their ideology (liberal) in a conservative state. Justice A just narrowly won her reelection with 51% of the vote; Justice B is up for reelection in two years; and Justice C does not face the voters for another four years. Electoral competition will affect the judicial behavior of these judges, each in a different way. Suppose there is a case before 155 the court in which the justices are inclined to support one position, while the electorate supports the opposite position. Justice A, given that she has just narrowly won election, may be more inclined to support a position different than her own preferred position, and consistent with the electorate that just returned her to office. Justice B, coming up for election in two years and having just seen the competitive race that Justice A was in, is unlikely to take a position on a controversial issue that is at odds with the preferences of the electorate if she hopes to retain her seat. Finally, Justice C is least likely to be affected by electoral politics. Even though she has to face the electorate to retain her seat, this election is not for another four years. She does not face any immediate sanction for her position. The above example illustrates how electoral politics can affect different justices sitting on the same high court. Electoral politics can also affect state supreme court outcomes across states. Justices in states with little electoral competition and longer terms of office can act in ways that are not consonant with the electorate with more frequency than justices in states with higher levels of competition and shorter terms of office. Thus, we would expect state supreme court decisions in states with shorter terms and higher levels of competition to be more congruent with the preferences of the electorate than state supreme court decisions in states with longer terms of office and lower levels of electoral competition. Clearly, the presence (or absence) of electoral competition plays a vital role in the behavior of state supreme court justices. This makes understanding the factors that influence electoral competition imperative to understanding the politics of state supreme courts. 156 State Supreme Court Election Reform Of course, all of this relates back to the independence versus accountability debate discussed in Chapter 1. The results suggest that under some circumstances campaign spending promotes state supreme court justices being held accountable by the electorate. That is, campaign spending is not necessarily a negative aspect of state supreme court elections. While it is true that raising and spending money raises the appearance of impropriety in some cases, the acts of raising and spending money also promote electoral competition, at least when this is done by candidates relatively unknown to the electorate. Given the recent United States Supreme Court decision in Republican Party v. White, campaign spending is likely to become even more important in promoting electoral competition as restrictions on what candidates can, and cannot say, are lifted. It is important to note that this dissertation does not speak to the debate over whether judges should, or should not, be elected. Indeed, this project is agnostic about the normative debate. Whether or not one method of judicial selection is “better” than another is a question I do not address. I treat state supreme court elections as a given, and seek to develop models that explain electoral competition in them. And, given that there are state supreme court elections, the results indicate that campaign spending can lead to judges being held more accountable by the electorate. Given the primacy of electoral accountability to the rationale behind judicial elections, this is a significant finding. The findings of this study point to several implications for the conduct, and potential reform, of state supreme court elections. First, it should be noted that the 157 insignificance of incumbent spending does not mean that incumbent spending is irrelevant or inconsequential. Surely, incumbents would have a difficult time getting reelected if they spent no money. The finding that incumbent spending does not affect their vote total is best interpreted in light of the advantages with which they begin the campaign. Challenger spending is seen as a sign of strength; the more money a challenger spends, the more viable her candidacy. Contrary to challengers, incumbent spending is not a sign of strength; rather, since they begin the campaign with large advantages in terms of experience, visibility, and so forth, high levels of incumbent spending are a sign of weakness (Jacobson 1980, 1985, 1997). The more threatened an incumbent feels (and thus the more likely it is that her race will be close), the more money she spends. Thus, the more money an incumbent spends, the lower her vote total is likely to be. This is not due to the amount of money spent by the incumbent, however, but is a result of the competitive nature of the race. The election of judges arose out of the need for courts to be independent from legislatures. Somewhat ironically given the current climate, the legal profession hailed the election of judges (Sheldon and Maule 1997). Now, there is growing concern about the election of judges, with many arguing that judicial elections must either be heavily regulated or eradicated (Schotland 1985 , 2001; Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review 2001; Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002). As was discussed earlier, there is much debate in state legislatures over the current climate of state supreme court elections. The results presented here suggest that any attempt to limit the amount of money spent in these elections will lead to less, and not more, competitive elections. Incumbent candidates are not able to increase their level of electoral support by spending more money, but 158 challengers are; winning candidates are not able to increase their vote total, but losers are. Those who decry the amounts of campaign spending in state supreme court elections (Hansen 1998; Glaberson 2000a, 2000b; Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review 2001; Goldberg, Holman, and Sanchez 2002) have overlooked the fact that campaign spending promotes electoral competition. Campaigns matter, and campaign spending is necessary for candidates to make themselves known to the electorate (Jacobson 1980; Coleman and Manna 2000). This is especially true since campaign spending benefits those candidates with whom the electorate is unfamiliar (usually nonincumbents) (Jacobson 1980; Alvarez 1997). Attempts to curb the amount of campaign spending are likely to only reinforce the incumbency advantage, and suppress electoral competition. The results also suggest that certain institutional reforms can promote competition, while others will have no effect or discourage it. Arkansas is moving to nonpartisan statewide single-member districts in 2002 (from partisan statewide single- member districts). The results here suggest that this will lead to less competition (since Chapter 4 indicates that nonpartisan elections are generally less competitive than partisan elections). However, there will be more spending (Chapter 5) in these nonpartisan races than there was in partisan races. Further, there will be no change on the influence of campaign spending on electoral outcomes (Chapter 7). Campaign spending by the challenger (incumbent-challenger races) and the loser (open seat contests) will continue to adversely affect the electoral performance of the incumbent (or winner). If the motivation behind the reform was to decrease electoral competition (and thus increase electoral independence), then it will likely be successful; however, if the purpose for the change in selection system was to lower the cost of these races or to decrease the 159 influence of campaign spending on the electoral support of the candidates, then the success of the reform is doubtful. The results also provide some comfort to those who think that the incumbency advantage is insurmountable. For a candidate seeking to unseat an incumbent, she can increase her vote total simply by spending more money. Additionally, there are other factors within her control that can contribute to her success. For example, if she has prior judicial experience, she will gain more votes, as she will if there was a recent close race for the state high court bench, if the incumbent is older, or if the incumbent was initially appointed to her seat on the high court bench. This suggests that challengers will perform better if they are somewhat selective in their decisions to run (Banks and Kiewiet 1989; Jacobson 1989; Bonneau and Hall 2000, 2001). In addition to candidate characteristics, the state and electoral context matters, as do the institutional structures of the election. If all else fails, however, the results here suggest that a candidate who is able to spend freely is able to increase her vote total by a significant amount. Future Research While this dissertation represents the most comprehensive examination of electoral competition and the role of campaign spending in state supreme court elections to date, it certainly is not the end of such inquiry. There is much more to be done before we can fully understand the dynamics of elections to the state high court bench. First, this dissertation has not said anything about campaign contributions. In order for candidates to spend money, they must have money. In Chapter 2, I talked a little bit about the importance contributors play in the electoral process. Contributors 160 give money for a variety of reasons; however, very few of them give money to candidates who are not viable. It is an open question as to what makes a potential candidate viable. Understanding what makes candidates viable is important because knowing what factors contributors look for in a candidate would help us understand how candidates attract money. Further, given a candidate with certain characteristics, we would be able to predict how much money she would be able to raise (and thus spend) as well as how well she would do against an incumbent. Not all candidates are equal, and understanding what makes candidates more attractive to contributors would help us assess the potential electability of these candidates. Second, there is the issue of how money affects judicial decision-making. We have seen in this dissertation how campaign spending can affect the electoral support of the candidate. In addition to concern over the influence of money on the electoral process, there are those who are worried about the influence of money on the judicial decision-making process. After all, if a candidate won her election due to campaign spending (at least in part), then she may reward her contributors once she ascends to the bench. To date, there is little evidence that justices give preferential treatment to their contributors (Bell 2002), although anecdotal evidence of such favoritism abounds (Campbell 1998; Robison 1998; Choate 2000a, 2000b; Farmer 2001; Marks and Hoke 2002; Popkey 2001; Scarritt 2001; Wersal 2001). At the very least, an appearance of such favoritism exists, something that has not gone unnoticed by judges, lawyers, and even the general public 01V ohl 2000; Glaberson 2000a; Dickerson 2001b; Marks 2001; Marks and Hoke 2001; Wickline 2001; Phillips 2002). Ascertaining if, and to what extent, campaign contributors are rewarded for their contributions once their candidate 161 ascends to the bench is a fundamental question that goes to the heart of the integrity of the bench. Unlike congressional and state legislative elections, state supreme court elections have been relatively ignored in the political science literature despite not only their importance, but also their analytical leverage. This dissertation has shown that both electoral competition and campaign spending, as well as the effects of campaign spending on electoral competition, vary according to institutional arrangements, along with characteristics of the candidate and state. While there is more to be done, this dissertation has shown the relevance of institutional structures on such fundamental electoral variables as competition and campaign spending, as well as the importance of understanding electoral competition and its consequences for the state high court bench. 162 APPENDDC 163 Table A.1: OLS results for Table 5.3 Variable Coefficient Robust z P > |z| Std. Error Open Seat 0.119 0.172 0.693 0.497 Appointed -0.108 0.177 -0.611 0.548 First Margin of -0.026 0.003 -8.599 0.000 Victory Control of 0.243 0.171 1.419 0.172 Court Number of -0.225 0.079 -2.860 0.010 Seats Partisan -0.030 0.281 -0.107 0.916 District 0047 0.278 -0.168 0.868 DistPart -0.062 0.366 -0.169 0.867 MultiMember -0.071 0.359 -0.198 0.845 Term 0.201 0.073 2.768 0.012 Voting Age 0.000 0.000 0.969 0.344 Population Prior Close 0.215 0.124 1.726 0.101 Race Tort Docket 0.055 0.005 11.875 0.000 1990 -0.746 0.219 -3.407 0.003 1992 -0.454 0.256 -1.772 0.092 1994 -0.206 0.223 -0.926 0.366 1996 -0.465 0.143 -3.242 0.004 1998 -0.032 0.135 -0.236 0.816 Constant 10.989 0.698 15.741 0.000 Dependent variable: log of total spending in the election Mean of dependent variable: 12.825 N=202 F(18, 19) = 180.35 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.6078 Root MSE = 0.7921 164 Table A2: Hausman Test Results for Table 6.2 Variable 2SLS OLS ZSLS — OLS S.E. Log of Incum. 3.093 0.425 2.668 6.732 Spending Log of Chall. -1.578 -1.323 -0.254 0.599 Spending Quality Chall. -4.961 -4.287 -0.674 1.737 Partisan 0.351 0.754 -0.403 1.127 Consonance Age 0005 -0.007 0.002 0.004 Appointed -3.186 -3442 0.255 .‘ First Compete -0.269 -0.065 -0.204 Prior Close -3.786 -4.086 0.301 Race Control of 0.272 0.790 -0.518 1.581 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 -0.000 0.000 Population Murder Rate —0.201 -0.049 -0.151 0.345 Tort Docket -0.030 0.096 -0.125 0.311 1990 -0.779 -3.276 2.497 6.079 1992 -0.890 -3.691 2.801 6.171 1994 -0.718 -2.511 1.793 3.165 1996 -2.161 -3.370 1.209 1.777 1998 4.252 3.540 0.712 2.130 Constant 40.623 66.297 -25.673 64.751 Ho = difference in the coefficients is not systematic x2 (14) = (B. - B.)’ (V. — V0403. - B.) where B, = the coefficient vector from ZSLS [‘10 = the coefficient vector from OLS Vt = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from ZSLS Vo = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from OLS x2 (16) 0.12 Prob > 12 = 1.000 ' The missing value here is not that surprising. “This covariance matrix is guaranteed to be positive definite only asymptotically and assurances are not made about the diagonal elements. Negative values along the diagonal are possible (Stata 1999, 11). 165 Table A3: Hausman Test Results for Table 6.3 Variable 281.8 OLS 2SLS — OLS S.E. Log of Winner 11.067 0.919 10.148 18.013 Spending Log of Loser -2.772 -1.763 -1.009 1.706 Spending Quality 3.212 2.113 1.099 3.443 Winner Quality Loser -2.778 -0.823 -1.955 4.716 Partisan -3.743 -0.566 -3.177 6.202 Consonance Compete 1.870 -4.977 6.848 11.871 Prior Close 2.828 2.786 0.042 1.583 Race Control of 0.433 0.265 0.167 1.424 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 -0.000 0.000 Population Tort Docket -0.498 -0.062 -0.436 0.798 1990 4.554 2.958 1.596 4.384 1992 2.932 1.403 1.529 4.993 1994 -4.675 1.496 -6.170 10.651 1996 4.175 4.338 -0.164 1998 -2.051 -2.777 0.726 . Constant -37.746 65.316 -103.063 184.462 H0 = difference in the coefficients is not systematic x2 (12) = (B. - B.)’ (V. — vo)“(B. - B.) where B, = the coefficient vector from 2SLS [3,, = the coefficient vector from OLS V, = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from 2SLS Vo = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from OLS x2 (15) 0.73 Prob > x2 = 1.000 166 Table A.4: OLS Results for Table 6.2 Variable Coefficient Robust t P > It] Std. Error Log of Incum. 0.425 1.019 0.417 0.682 Spending Log of Chall. -1.323 0.531 -2.493 0.023 Spending Quality Chall. -4.287 2.419 -1.772 0.094 Partisan 0.754 0.958 0.787 0.442 Consonance Age -0.007 0.002 -3.104 0.006 Appointed -3.442 1.404 -2.451 0.025 First Compete -0.065 1.242 -0.052 0.959 Prior Close -4.086 1.642 -2.489 0.023 Race Control of 0.790 1.455 0.543 0.594 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 1.898 0.075 Population Murder Rate -0.049 0.187 -0.264 0.795 Tort Docket 0.096 0.083 1.155 0.264 1990 -3.276 1.537 —2. 131 0.048 1992 -3.691 2.354 -1.568 0.135 1994 -2.51 1 2.922 -0.860 0.402 1996 -3.370 3.236 -1.041 0.312 1998 3.540 2.443 1.449 0.166 Constant 66.297 8.966 7.394 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 N = 127 F (16, 17) = 423.68 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.4942 Root MSE = 8.281 167 Table A5: OLS Results for Table 6.3 Variable Coefficient Robust t P > M Std. Error Log of Winner 0.919 1.127 0.815 0.427 Spending Log of Loser -1.763 0.556 -3.172 0.006 Spending Quality 2.113 2.123 0.996 0.334 Winner Quality Loser -0.823 3.277 -0.251 0.805 Partisan -0.566 1.053 -0.537 0.598 Consonance Compete -4.977 2.866 -1.737 0.102 Prior Close 2.786 4.397 0.634 0.535 Race Control of 0.265 2.240 0.118 0.907 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 0.368 0.717 Population Tort Docket -0.062 0.116 -0.539 0.597 1990 2.958 4.799 0.616 0.546 1992 1.403 3.342 0.420 0.680 1994 1.496 2.610 0.573 0.575 1996 4.338 5.287 0.820 0.424 1998 -2.777 5.506 -0.504 0.621 Constant 65.316 16.616 3.931 0.001 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N=63 F (15, 16) = 131.78 Prob > F = 0.000 R2=0.3110 Root MSE=9.118 168 Table A6: OLS Results for Table 6.4 Variable Coefficient Robust t P > M Std. Error Log of Incum. 0.251 1.102 0.228 0.822 Spending Log of Chall. -1.156 0.544 -2.125 0.049 Spending Quality Chall. -5.058 2.347 -2.155 0.046 Partisan 0.422 1.087 0.388 0.703 Consonance Age 0007 0.002 -2.934 0.009 Appointed -3.835 1.651 -2.323 0.033 First Compete -0.145 1.352 -0.107 0.916 Prior Close -5.145 2.278 -2.259 0.037 Race Control of 1.384 2.046 0.676 0.508 Court ' Voting 0.000 0.000 1.391 0.182 Population Murder Rate 0.087 0.285 0.304 0.765 Tort Docket 0.079 0.097 0.815 0.426 1990 -5.639 2.899 -1.945 0.068 1992 -5 .484 3.503 -1.565 0.136 1994 -4.597 3.661 -1.256 0.226 1996 -5.304 3.761 -1.410 0.177 1998 1.887 3.255 0.580 0.570 Constant 69.074 10.432 6.621 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 N = 115 F (16, 17) = 1914.66 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.4874 Root MSE = 8.465 169 Table A.7: OLS Results for Table 6.5 Variable Coefficient Robust t P > M Std. Error Log of Winner 0.927 1.103 0.840 0.413 Spending Log of Loser -1.762 0.563 -3.130 0.006 Spending Quality 2.118 2.160 0.980 0.341 Winner Quality Loser -0.794 3.048 -0.260 0.798 Partisan -0.571 1.030 -0.554 0.587 Consonance Compete -4.949 2.757 -1.795 0.092 Prior Close 2.844 5.087 0.559 0.584 Race Control of 0.268 2.278 0.118 0.908 Court Voting 0.000 0.000 0.317 0.756 Population Tort Docket -0.061 0.108 -0.564 0.580 1990 2.871 5.426 0.529 0.604 1992 1.336 3.839 0.348 0.732 1994 1.426 3.268 0.436 0.668 1996 4.274 6.004 0.712 0.487 1998 -2.855 6.611 -0.432 0.672 Constant 65.200 16.472 3.958 0.001 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 55.87 N = 61 F (15, 16) = 131.780 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.3111 Root MSE = 9.317 170 Table A8: Chow Test Results for Table 7.2 Model Estimated Sum of Squares df Partisan 6844.093 20 Nonpartisan 2760.339 20 Full 8018.447 20 Chow Test: ESS(F) - (ESS(P) — ESS(N)) / l_( ESS(P) + ESS(N) / n(P) + n(N) - 2(k) [8018.447 — (6844.093 + 2760.339)l / 20 (6844.093 + 2760.339) / [(58 + 69) — 2(20)] F (k, n(P)+n(N)-2(k) = F (20,87) F (20, 87) = -0.718 Thus, cannot reject the hypothesis that the regressions are the same (Gujarati 1995) 171 Table A9: Hausman Test Results for Table 7.2 Variable 2SLS OLS ZSLS — OLS SE. Log of Incum. 1.138 -0.188 1.326 3.592 Spending Log of Chall. -1.634 -1.522 -0.112 0.247 Spending Quality Chall. —4. 103 -3.858 -0.245 0.665 Partisan -0.513 -0.384 -0.129 Consonance Age 0005 -0.006 0.001 0.001 Appointed -2.950 -3.123 0.173 0.275 First Compete 1.278 1.402 -0.124 0.514 Prior Close 4.570 -4.631 0.061 0.099 Race Control of 0.190 0.421 -0.231 1.043 Court Voting 0.000 0.001 -0.000 Population Murder Rate 0.259 0.366 -0.107 0.345 Tort Docket 0.099 0.165 -0.066 0.181 Partisan -3.136 -3.616 0.480 0.979 District -6.357 -6.619 0.262 0.746 MultiMember 0.625 -0.113 0.738 1.798 Term 2.430 2.624 -0.194 0.468 1990 -3.329 -4.510 1.181 3.078 1992 -3.266 -4.633 1.366 3.991 1994 -2.336 -3.166 0.831 3.034 1996 -3.171 -3.775 0.604 1.767 1998 4.277 4.001 0.277 1.270 Constant 44.474 55.936 -11.462 31.797 H0 = difference in the coefficients is not systematic x2 (10) = (B. - B.)' (V. — V.)"(B. - B.) where ,= the coefficient vector from 2SLS 130 = the coefficient vector from OLS V, = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from 281.8 Vo = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from OLS x2 (19) = 0.022 2 In this case, the model does not meet the assumptions of the Hausman test. This can be interpreted as “strong evidence that we cannot reject the null hypothesis. Such a result is not an unusual outcome for the Hausman test, particularly when the sample is relatively small ...” (Stata 1999, 12). 172 Table A. 10: Hausman Test Results for Table 7.4 Variable 2SLS OLS 2SLS — OLS SE. Log of Winner 5.463 0.130 5.333 9.940 Spending Log of Loser -2.253 -1.928 -0.325 0.998 Spending Quality Winner 1.210 0.679 0.531 1.696 Quality Loser -0. 160 1.606 -1.767 5.044 Partisan -1.546 -0.702 -0.843 1.564 Consonance Compete -0.499 -2.778 2.279 3.156 Prior Close 3.588 5.223 -1.635 2.922 Race Control of -0.642 -0.022 -0.621 1.115 Court Voting 0.000 —0.000 0.000 0.000 Population Tort Docket -0.232 0.004 -0.235 0.455 Partisan -2.894 -2.429 0.465 . District 5.781 0.579 5.201 9.219 MultiMember 11.198 12.584 -1.387 5.522 Term 0879 -0.041 -0.837 1.587 1990 2.341 2.270 0.071 . 1992 0.239 1.239 -1.000 2.164 1994 -3.431 0.049 -3.480 6.970 1996 4.609 2.730 1.879 1998 -0.920 -2.024 1.104 . Constant 25.210 75 .703 -50.493 88.625 Ho = difference in the coefficients is not systematic x2 (18) = (B. - B.)’ (V. — V.)“(B. - B.) where B, = the coefficient vector from 2SLS 0,, = the coefficient vector from OLS V, = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from 281.8 Vo = the covariance matrix of the coefficients from OLS x2 (18) = -0423 x 3 . . . . In this case, the model does not meet the assumptions of the Hausman test. Thrs can be interpreted as ‘Strong evidence that we cannot reject the null hypothesis. Such a result is not an unusual outcome for the I‘lausman test, particularly when the sample is relatively small (Stata 1999, 12). 173 Table A. 1 1: OLS Results for Table 7.2 Variable Coefficient Robust t P > M Std. Error Log of Incum. -0.188 0.965 -0.194 0.848 Spending Log of Chall. -1.522 0.537 -2.832 0.011 Spending Quality Chall. -3.858 2.367 -1.630 0.121 Partisan -0.384 1.128 -0.340 0.738 Consonance Age 0006 0.002 -2.736 0.014 Appointed -3.123 1.244 -2.511 0.022 First Compete 1.402 1.236 1.135 0.272 Prior Close -4.631 1.583 —2.925 0.009 Race Control of 0.421 1.852 0.227 0.823 Court Voting 0.001 0.000 1.887 0.076 Population Murder Rate 0.366 0.325 1.124 0.277 Tort Docket 0.165 0.065 2.544 0.021 Partisan -3.616 2.256 -1.603 0.127 District -6.619 3.067 -2.159 0.045 MultiMember -0.113 3.011 -0.037 0.971 Term 2.624 0.662 3.961 0.001 1990 -4.510 1.851 -2.437 0.026 1992 —4.633 2.294 -2.019 0.060 1994 -3.166 2.989 -1.060 0.304 1996 -3.775 3.180 -1.187 0.252 1998 4.001 2.271 1.761 0.096 Constant 55.936 9.360 5.976 0.000 Dependent variable: percentage of vote for incumbent Mean of dependent variable: 56.31 N = 127 F (16, 17) = 71.77 Prob > F = 0.000 R2 = 0.5516 Root MSE = 7.944 174 REFERENCES Abramowitz, Alan I. 1975. “Name Familiarity, Reputation, and the Incumbency Effect in a Congressional Election.” Western Political Quarterly 28 (December): 668-682. Abramowitz, Alan I. 1988. “Explaining Senate Election Outcomes.” American Political Science Review 82 (June): 385-403. Abramowitz, Alan I. 1989. “Campaign Spending in United States Senate Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 14 (November): 487-507. Achen, Christopher H. 1986. The Statistical Analysis of Quasi-Experiments. Berkeley: University of California Press. Alexander, Herbert E. 1972. Money in Politics. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press. Alvarez, R. Michael. 1997. Information and Elections. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. American Bar Association. 1998. Report and Recommendations of the Task Force on Lawyers' Political Contributions: Part 11. Chicago, IL: American Bar Assocation. Ansolabehere, Stephen and Alan Gerber. 1994. “The Mismeasure of Campaign Spending: Evidence from the 1990 United States House Elections.” Journal of Politics 56 (November): 1106-1118. Arrington, Theodore S. 1996. “When Money Doesn’t Matter: Campaign Spending for Minor Statewide Judicial and Executive Offices in North Carolina.” Justice System Journal 18 (3): 257-266. Aspin, Larry T. 1998. “Campaigns in Judicial Retention Elections: Do They Make a Difference.” Justice System Journal 20 (1): 1-15. Aspin, Larry T. and William K. Hall. 1987. “The Friends and Neighbors Effect in Judicial Retention Elections.” Western Political Quarterly 40 (December): 703-715. Aspin, Larry T. and William K. Hall. 1989. “Friends and Neighbors Voting in Judicial Retention Elections: A Research Note Comparing Trial and Appellate Court Elections.” Western Political Quarterly 42 (December): 587-595. Aspin, Larry T., William K. Hall, Jean Bax, and Celeste Montoya. 2000. “Thirty Years of Judicial Retention Elections: An Update.” The Social Science Journal 37 (January): 1-17. 175 Atkeson, Lonna Rae and Randall W. Partin. 1995. “Economic and Referendum Voting: A Comparison of Gubernatorial and Senate Elections.” American Political Science Review 89 (March): 99-107. Banaian, King and William A. Luksetich. 1991. “Campaign Spending in Congressional Elections.” Economic Inquiry 29 (January): 92-100. Banks, Jeffrey S. and D. Roderick Kiewiet. 1989. “Explaining Patterns of Candidate Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (November): 997-1015. Beck, Nathaniel and Jonathan N. Katz. 1995. “What To Do (and Not To Do) with Time- Series Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89 (September): 634- 647. Becker, Lee B. and Sharon Dunwoody. 1982. “Media Use, Public Affairs Knowledge and Voting in Local Elections.” Journalism Quarterly 59 (2): 212-218. Bell, Dawson. 2001. “En gler to Ask for Appointed High Court.” The Detroit Free Press, January 27. Bell, Dawson. 2002. “Good News About Judicial Fairness Gets Overlooked.” The Detroit Free Press, March 25. Berry, Ertel. 2001. “Party Labels Outweighed War Chests in 2000 High Court Races.” North Carolina Lawyers Weekly 14 (April 2): 37. Biersack, Robert, Paul S. Hermson, and Clyde Wilcox. 1993. “Seeds for Success: Early Money in Congressional Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 18 (November): 535- 551. Bonneau, Chris W. 2001a. “The Composition of State Supreme Courts, 2000.” Judicature 85 (July-August): 26-31. Bonneau, Chris W. 2001b. “Money and Votes in State Supreme Court Elections.” Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 30-September 2, 2001, San Francisco, California. Bonneau, Chris W. and Melinda Gann Hall. 2000. “Challengers in State Supreme Court Elections.” Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 27-30, 2000, Chicago, Illinois. Bonneau, Chris W. and Melinda Gann Hall. 2001. “Incumbents, Challengers, and the Politics of Judicial Elections.” Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 19-22, 2001, Chicago, Illinois. 176 Brace, Paul. 2002. Personal Communication. September 10. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 1990. “Neo-Institutionalism and Dissent in State Supreme Courts.” Journal of Politics 52 (February): 54-70. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 1995. “Studying Courts Comparatively: The View from the American States.” Political Research Quarterly 48 GVIarch): 5-29. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 1997. ”The Interplay of Preferences, Case Facts, Context, and Structure in the Politics of Judicial Choice.” Journal of Politics 59 (November): 1206-1231. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 2000a. “Comparing Courts Using the American States.” Judicature 83 (March-April): 250-266. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 2000b. “Courts as Agents of Continuity and Change: Winning an Losing in State Supreme Courts.” Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 31-September 3, Washington, DC. Brace, Paul and Melinda Gann Hall. 2001. “‘Haves’ Versus ‘Have Nots’ in State Supreme Courts: Allocating Docket Space and Wins in Power Asymmetric Cases.” law and Society Review 35 (2): 393-417. Breaux, David A. and Anthony Gierzynski. 1991. “‘It’s Money That Matters’: Campaign Expenditures and State Legislative Primaries.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 16 (August): 429-443. Breen. Richard. 1996. Regression Models: Censored, Sample Selected, or Truncated Data. London: Sage. Brown, TC. 2000. “Resnick Overcomes Ads, Wins Supreme Court Race.” The Cleveland Plain Dealer, November 8. Brubaker, Stanley C. 1998. “The Limits of Campaign Spending Limits.” The Public Interest 133 (Fall): 33-54. Campbell, Linda P. 1998. “Fund-Raising by Justices Gets Attention.” Fort Worth Star- Telegram, September 27. Carp, Robert A. and Ronald D. Stidham. 2001. Judicial Process in America, 5‘h edition. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Carsey, Thomas M., and Gerald R. Wright. 1998. “State and National Forces in Gubernatorial and Senate Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 42 (July): 994-1002. 177 Cassie, William E. and David A. Breaux. 1998. “Expenditures and Election Results.” In Campaign Finance in State Legislative Elections, edited by Joel A. Thompson and Gary P. Moncrief. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Champagne, Anthony. 1986. “The Selection and Retention of Judges in Texas.” Southwestern Law Journal 40: 53-117. Champagne, Anthony. 1992. “Campaign Contributions in Texas Supreme Court Races.” Crime, Law and Social Change 17 (March): 91-106. Champagne, Anthony and Kyle Cheek. 1996. “PACs and Judicial Politics in Texas.” Judicature 80 (J uly-August): 26-27. Champagne, Anthony and Greg Thielemann. 1991. “Awareness of Trial Court Judges.” Judicature 74 (February-March): 271-276. Cheek, Kyle and Anthony Champagne. 2000. “Money in Texas Supreme Court Elections.” Judicature 84 (J uly-August): 20-25. Choate, Alan. 2000a. “State GOP Executive Director Denounces Findings of Study, Author.” Mobile Register, October 31. Choate, Alan. 2000b. “Ads Link Supreme Court Justices to Firestone Controversy.” Mobile Register, November 2. Coleman, John J. and Paul F. Manna. 2000. “Congressional Campaign Spending and the Quality of Democracy.” Journal of Politics 62 (August): 757-789. Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press. Cox, Gary W. and Scott Morgenstem. 1995. “The Incumbency Advantage in Multimember Districts: Evidence from the US. States.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 20 (August): 329-349. Dickerson, Brian. 2001a. “Belatedly, Engler Seeks Court Reform.” The Detroit Free Press, January 29. Dickerson, Brian. 2001b. “Reason Rules Civil Reform on Judiciary.” The Detroit Free Press, February 12. Dubois, Philip L. 1979. “The Significance of Voting Cues in State Supreme Court Elections.” Law and Society Review 13 (Spring): 757-779. 178 Dubois, Philip L. 1980. From Ballot to Bench: Judicial Elections and the Quest for Accountability. Austin: University of Texas Press. Dubois, Philip L. 1984. “Voting Cues in Nonpartisan Trial Court Elections: A Multivariate Assessment.” Law and Society Review 18 (3): 395-436. Dubois, Philip L. 1986a. “Penny For Your Thoughts? Campaign Spending in California Trial Court Elections, 1976-1982.” Western Political Quarterly 39 (June): 265-284. Dubois, Philip L. 1986b. “Financing Trial Court Elections: Who Contributes to Califomia’s Judicial Campaigns.” Judicature 70 (June-July): 8-16. Erikson, Robert S. and Thomas R. Palfrey. 1998. “Campaign Spending and Incumbency: An Alternative Simultaneous Equations Approach.” Journal of Politics 60 (May): 355-373. Erikson, Robert S. and Thomas R. Palfrey. 2000. “Equilibria in Campaign Spending Games: Theory and Data.” American Political Science Review 94 (September): 595- 609. Farmer, John. 2001. “Justice For Sale in Pennsylvania.” Newark Star-Ledger, August 17. Ferejohn, John A. 1990. “Information and the Electoral Process.” In Information and Democratic Processes, edited by John A. Ferejohn and James H. Kuklinski. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press. Ferguson, Thomas. 1995. Golden Rule: The Investment Theory of Party Competition and the Logic of Money-Driven Political Systems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Friedman, Lawrence M. 1985. History of American Law. New York: Simon and Schuster. Friedrich, Robert J. 1982. “In Defense of Multiplicative Terms in Multiple Regression Equations.” American Journal of Political Science 26 (November): 797-833. Gerber, Alan. 1998. “Estimating the Effect of Campaign Spending on Senate Election Outcomes Using Instrumental Variables.” American Political Science Review 92 (June): 401-411. Gierzynski, Anthony. 1998. “A Framework for the Study of Campaign Finance.” In Campaign Finance in State Legislative Elections, edited by Joel A. Thompson and Gary F. Moncrief. Washington, DC: CQ Press. 179 Gierzynski, Anthony and David A. Breaux. 1991. “Money and Votes in State Legislative Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 16 (May): 203-217. Gierzynski, Anthony and David A. Breaux. 1993. “Money and the Party Vote in State House Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 18 (November): 515-533. Gierzynski, Anthony and David A. Breaux. 1996. “Legislative Elections and the Importance of Money.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 21 (August): 337-358. Gierzynski, Anthony, Paul Kleppner, and James Lewis. 1998. “Money or the Machine: Money and Votes in Chicago Aldermanic Elections.” American Politics Quarterly 26 (April): 160-173. Giles, Michael W. and Anita Pritchard. 1985. “Campaign Expenditures and Legislative Elections in Florida.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 10 (February): 71-88. Glaberson, William. 2000a. “Fierce Campaigns Signal a New Era for State Courts.” New York Times, June 5, 2000. Glaberson, William. 2000b. “State Chief Justices Plan to Meet on Judicial Candidates’ Abuses.” New York Times, September 8, 2000. Glaberson, William. 2001. “States Take Steps to Rein In Excesses of Judicial Politicking.” New York Times. June 15. Glick, Henry R. and Craig F. Emmert. 1987. “Selection Systems and Judicial Characteristics: The Recruitment of State Supreme Court Judges.” Judicature 70 (December-January): 228-235. Goldberg, Deborah, Craig Holman, and Samantha Sanchez. 2002. The New Politics of Judicial Elections. New York: Justice at Stake Campaign. Gopoian, J. David. 1984. “What Makes PACs Tick? An Analysis of the Allocation Patterns of Economic Interest Groups.” American Journal of Political Science 28 (May): 259-281. Green, Donald Philip and Jonathan S. Krasno. 1988. “Salvation for the Spendthrift Incumbent: Reestimating the Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 32 (November): 884-907. Green, Donald Philip and Jonathan S. Krasno. 1990. “Rebuttal to J acobson’s ‘New Evidence for Old Arguments.”’ American Journal of Political Science 32 (November): 884-907. Greene, William H. 2000. Econometric Analysis, 4‘11 edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. 180 Grier, Kevin B. and Michael C. Munger. 1986. “The Impact of Legislator Attributes on Interest-Group Campaign Contributions.” Journal of Labor Research 7 (Fall): 349-361. Griffin, Kenyon N. and Michael J. Horan. 1979. “Merit Retention Elections: What Influences the Voters?” Judicature 63 (August): 78-88. Gujarati, Damodar N. 1995. Basic Econometrics, 3rd edition. New York: McGraw Hill. Hall, Melinda Gann. 1987. “Constituent Influence in State Supreme Courts: Conceptual Notes and a Case Study.” Journal of Politics 49 (November): 1117-1124. Hall, Melinda Gann. 1992. “Electoral Politics and Strategic Voting in State Supreme Courts.” Journal of Politics 54 (May): 427-446. Hall, Melinda Gann. 1995. “Justices as Representatives: Elections and Judicial Politics in the American States.” American Politics Quarterly 23 (October): 485-503. Hall, Melinda Gann. 2000. State Supreme Court Elections Data, 1990-1995. East Lansing, MI: Michigan State University. Hall, Melinda Gann. 2001a. “State Supreme Courts in American Democracy: Probing the Myths of Judicial Reform.” American Political Science Review 95 (June): 315-330. Hall, Melinda Gann. 2001b. “Voluntary Retirements from State Supreme Courts: Assessing Democratic Pressures to Relinquish the Bench.” Journal of Politics 63 (November): 1 112-1140. Hall, Melinda Gann and Chris W. Bonneau. 2000. “The Wisconsin Judiciary.” In Wisconsin Government and Politics, 7‘h edition, edited by Ronald E. Weber. New York: McGraw-Hill. Hall, Melinda Gann and Paul Brace. 1989. “Order in the Courts: A Neo-Institutional Approach to Judicial Consensus.” Western Political Quarterly 42 (September): 391-407. Hall, Melinda Gann and Paul Brace. 1992. “Toward an Integrated Model of Judicial Voting Behavior.” American Politics Quarterly 20 (April): 147-168. Hall, Melinda Gann and Paul Brace. 1999. “State Supreme Courts and Their Environments: Avenues to General Theories of Judicial Choice.” In Supreme Court Decision-Making: New Institutionalist Approaches, edited by Cornell W. Clayton and Howard Gillman. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hall, Richard L. 1996. Participation in Congress. New Haven: Yale University Press. 181 Hall, Richard L. and Frank W. Wayman. 1990. “Buying Time: Moneyed Interests and the Mobilization of Bias in Congressional Committees.” American Political Science Review 84 (September): 797-820. Hansen, Mark. 1998. “A Run for the Bench.” ABA Journal 84 (October): 68-72. Heard, Alexander. 1960. The Costs of Democracy. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press. Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47 (January): 153-162. Hogan, Robert E. and Keith E. Hamm. 1998. “Variations in District-Level Campaign Spending in State Legislatures.” In Campaign Finance in State Legislative Elections, edited by Joel A. Thompson and Gary P. Moncrief. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Holbrook, Thomas M. and Emily Van Dunk. 1993. “Electoral Competition in the American States.” American Political Science Review 87 (December): 955-962. Jackson, Donald W. and James W. Riddlesperger, Jr. 1991. “Money and Politics in Judicial Elections: The 1988 Election of the Chief Justice of the Texas Supreme Court.” Judicature 74 (December-January): 184-189. Jacobson, Gary C. 1978. “The Effects of Campaign Spending in Congressional Elections.” American Political Science Review 72 (June): 469-491. Jacobson, Gary C. 1980. Money in Congressional Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press. Jacobson, Gary C. 1981. “Incumbents’ Advantages in the 1978 US. Congressional Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 6 (May): 183-200. Jacobson, Gary C. 1985. “Money and Votes Reconsidered: Congressional Elections, 1972-1982.” Public Choice 47 ( 1): 7-62. Jacobson, Gary C. 1989. “Strategic Politicians and the Dynamics of US. House Elections, 1946-1986.” American Political Science Review 83 (September): 773-793. Jacobson, Gary C. 1990. “The Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections: New Evidence for Old Arguments.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (May): 334- 362. Jacobson, Gary C. 1996. ”The 1994 House Elections in Perspective.” Political Science Quarterly 111 (Spring): 203-223. 182 Jacobson, Gary C. 1997. The Politics of Congressional Elections, 4th edition. New York: Longman. Jewell, Malcolm E. 1982. Representation in State Legislatures. Lexington, KY: University Press of Kentucky. Johnson, Charles A., Roger C. Schaefer, R. Neal McKnight. 1978. “The Salience of Judicial Candidates and Elections.” Social Science Quarterly 59 (June): 371-378. Kennedy, Peter. 1998. A Guide to Econometrics, 3rd edition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Key, V.O., Jr. 1961 Public Opinion and American Democracy. New York: Alfred A. Knopf. Klein, David and Lawrence Baum. 2001. “Ballot Information and Voting Decisions in Judicial Elections.” Political Research Quarterly 54 (December): 709-728. Klots, Allen T. 1955. “The Selection of Judges and the Short Ballot.” Journal of the American Judicature Society 38: 134-140. Langer, Laura. 2002. Judicial Review in State Supreme Courts: A Comparative Study. Albany: SUNY Press. Lee, Frances E. and Bruce I. Oppenheimer. 1999. Sizing Up the Senate: The Unequal Consequences of Equal Representation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Levitt, Steven D. 1994. “Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending on Election Outcomes in the US. House.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (August): 777-798. Lowry, Robert C., James E. Alt, and Karen E. Ferree. 1998. “Fiscal Policy Outcomes and Electoral Accountability in American States.” American Political Science Review 92 (December): 759-774. Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review. 2001. “Symposium: National Summit on Improving Judicial Selection.” Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review 34 (June): 1353-1512. Marks, Lynn. 2001. “Perspectives: Odor in the Courts.” Pittsburgh Post-Gazette, November 5. Marks, Lynn A. and Julia H. Hoke. 2001. “Electing Judges: Had Enough, Yet?” Philadelphia Daily News, November 9. Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press. 183 McKnight, R. Neal, Roger Schaefer, and Charles A. Johnson. 1978. “Choosing Judges: DO the Voters Know What They’re Doing?” Judicature 62 (August): 94-99. Miller, Gary J ., Thomas H. Hammond, and Charles Kile. 1996. “Bicameralism and the Core: An Experimental Test.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 21 (February): 83-103. Mikva, Abner and William 8. Sessions. 2001. “Guarantee the Independence of All Judges.” Los Angeles Times, March 31. Moe, Terry M. 1987. “An Assessment of the Positive Theory of ‘Congressional Dominance.’” Legislative Studies Quarterly 12 (November): 475-520. Moncrief, Gary F. 2001. Personal Communication. November 13. Moog, Robert. 1992. “Campaign Financing for North Carolina’s Appellate Courts.” Judicature 76 (August-September): 68-76. Munger, Michael C. 1989. “A Simple Test of the Thesis that Committee Jurisdictions Shape Corporate PAC Contributions.” Public Choice 62 (August): 181-186. Nicholson, Marlene Arnold and Norman Nicholson. 1994. “Funding Judicial Campaigns in Illinois.” Judicature 77 (May-June): 294-299. Niemi, Richard 6., Harold W. Stanley, and Ronald J. Vogel. 1995. “State Economies and State Taxes: Do Voters Hold Governors Accountable?” American Journal of Political Science 39 (November): 936-957. Omdorff, Mary. 2002. “State Justices Races Most Costly in US.” The Birmingham News, April 1. Palda, Filip. 1994. How Much Is Your Vote Worth? The Unfaimess of Campaign Spending Limits. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies. Partin, Randall W. 2002. “Assessing the Impact of Campaign Spending in Governors’ Races.” Political Research Quarterly 55 (March): 213-233. Phillips, Thomas R. 2002. “When Money Talks, the Judiciary Must Balk.” Washington Post, April 14. Pittsburgh Post-Gazette. 2001a. “Editorial: Throw Out the Baby.” Pittsburgh Post- Gazette, January 17. Pittsburgh Post-Gazette. 2001b. “Editorial: Ridge the Reformer.” Pittsburgh Post- Gazette, February 14. 184 Pittsburgh Post-Gazette. 20010. “Editorial: Judging an Opportunity.” Pittsburgh Post- Gazette, April 13. Pomper, Gerald M. 1968. Elections in America: Control and Influence in Democratic Politics. New York: Dodd, Mead & Company. Popkey, Dan. 2001. “Contributors Could Benefit from Eismann’s Role.” The Idaho Statesman, March 8. Przeworski, Adam and Henry Teune. 1970. The Logic of Comparative Social Inquiry. Malabar, FL: Krieger. Reid, Traciel V. 1996. “PAC Participation in North Carolina Supreme Court Elections.” Judicature 80 (July—August): 21-29. Reid, Tracie] V. 1999. “The Politicization of Retention Elections: Lessons from the Defeat of Justices Lanphier and White.” Judicature 83 (September-October): 68-77. Robison, Clay. 1998. “‘Payola Justice’ in Texas Revisited.” Houston Chronicle, November 2. Rohde, David W. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Romer, Thomas and James M. Snyder, Jr. 1994. “An Empirical Investigation of the Dynamics of PAC Contributions.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (August): 745-769. Sayrs, Louis W. 1989. Pooled Time Series Analysis. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Scarritt, Tom. 2001. “Who Holds the Gavel in Alabama?” The Birmingham News, April 1. Schaffner, Brian F., Matthew Streb, and Gerald Wright. 2001. “Teams Without Uniforms: The Nonpartisan Ballot in State and Local Elections.” Political Research Quraterly 54 (March): 7-30. Schotland, Roy A. 1985. “Elective Judges’ Campaign Financing: Are State Judges’ Robes the Emperor’s Clothes of American Democracy.” Journal of Law and Politics 2 (Spring): 57-167. Schotland, Roy A. 2001. “Financing Judicial Elections, 2000: Change and Challenge.” The Law Review of Michigan State University—Detroit College of Law 2001 (Fall): 849- 899. 185 Sheldon, Charles H. and Linda S. Maule. 1997. Choosing Justice: The Recruitment of State and Federal Judges. Pullman, WA: Washington State University Press. Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Barry R. Weingast. 1987. “The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power.” American Political Science Review 81 (March): 85-104. Smith, Bradley A. 1996. “Faulty Assumptions and Undemocratic Consequences of Campaign Finance Reform.” Yale Law Journal 105 (January): 1049-1091. 9 Smith, Bradley A. 1999. “Some Problems with Taxpayer-Funded Political Campaigns.’ University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148 (December): 591-628. Sorauf, Frank J. 1988. Money in American Elections. Glenview, IL: Soctt, Foresman. Sorauf, Frank J. 1992. Inside Campaign Finance: Myths and Realities. New Haven: Yale University Press. Squire, Peverill. 1989a. “Competition and Uncontested Seats in US. House Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 14 (May): 281-295. Squire, Peverill. 1989b. “Challengers in US. Senate Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 14 (November): 531-547. Squire, Peverill. 1992. “Challenger Quality and Voting Behavior in US. Senate Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 17 (May): 247-263. Squire, Peverill. 1995. “Candidates, Money, and Voters—Assessing the State of Congressional Elections Research.” Political Research Quarterly 48 (December): 891- 917. Squire, Peverill. 2000. “Uncontested Seats in State Legislative Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 25 (February): 131-146. Squire, Peverill and John R. Wright. 1990. “Fundraising by Nonincumbent Candidates for the US. House of Representatives.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 15 (February): 89- 98. STATA. 1999. Stata Reference Manual Release 6, Volume 2. College Station, TX: Stata Press. Stimson, James A. 1985. “Regression in Space and Time: A Statistical Essay.” American Journal of Political Science 29 (November): 914-947. Su, Tie-ting, Alan Neustadtl, and Don Clawson. 1995. “Business and the Conservative Shift: Corporate PAC Contributions, 1976-1986.” Social Science Quarterly 76 (March): 20-40. 186 Svoboda, Craig J. 1995. “Retrospective Voting in Gubernatorial Elections: 1982 and 1986.” Political Research Quarterly 48 (March): 135-150. Swerczek, Mary. 2001. “Weimer to Sit on Supreme Court: Voting Light, Close for 6th District Seat.” The New Orleans Times-Picayune, November 18. Thielemann, Gregory S. 1993. “Local Advantage in Campaign Financing: Friends, Neighbors, and Their Money in Texas Supreme Court Elections.” Journal of Politics 55 (May): 472-478. Thielemann, John and Allen Wilhite. 1995. “Congressional Turnover: Negating the Incumbency Advantage.” Social Science Quarterly 76 (September): 594-606. Thomas, Scott J. 1989. “Do Incumbent Campaign Expenditures Matter?” Journal of Politics 51 (November): 965-976. Tucker, Harvey J. and Ronald E. Weber. 1987. “State Legislative Election Outcomes: Contextual Effects and Legislative Performance Effects.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 12 (November): 537-553. Van Dunk, Emily. 1997. “Challenger Quality in State Legislative Elections.” Political Research Quarterly 50 (September): 793-807. Weber, Ronald E., Harvey J. Tucker, and Paul Brace. 1991. “Vanishing Marginals in State Legislative Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 16 (February): 29-48. Welch, W. P. 1976. “The Effectiveness of Expenditures in State Legislative Races.” American Politics Quarterly 4 (July): 333-356. Welch, William P. 1979. “Patterns of Contributions: Economic Interest and Ideological Groups.” In Political Finance, edited by Herbert Alexander. Beverly Hills: Sage. Welch, W. P. 1981. “Money and Votes: A Simultaneous Equation Model.” Public Choice 36: 209-234. Wenzel, Fritz. 2001. “Judicial Experts at UT Law Forum Divided on Value of Elected Bench.” The Toledo Blade, March 31. Wersal, Greg. 2001. “Counterpoint: See Why Minnesota’s Judiciary Could Use Campaign Reform.” Minneapolis-St. Paul Star-Tribune, March 10. Wertheimer, Fred and Susan W. Manes. 1994. “Campaign Finance Reform: A Key to Restoring the Health of Our Democracy.” Columbia University Law Review 94 (May): 1126-1159. 187 Wickline, Michael R. 2001. “Arkansas Faces Shift in Judicial Elections.” Arkansas Democrat-Gazette, May 20. Wohl, Alexander. 2000. “Justice for Rent: The Scandal of Judicial Campaign Financing.” American Prospect 11 (May 22): 34-37. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2000. Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach. Cincinnati, OH: South-Westem College. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge: MIT Press. 188