.1»: :1 .._ 4. .....% u- ..r. ‘ .41 .1 Ah W r 1.993 7 .4. tag GM“ . ma .. o . r .r...&. #5qu .5 . 3. ...Z . .2 . r: ”humufluw i)... .332,” ”an; $.13. 14 .o. . FwMian 1.2» a. A . Hutuflnw. .. {1 are] . , ‘ . Mwmfimmfi ‘n. . .. u if}. , 1.1352 ‘ . ‘ , Q . -. V 90.13932: .51“ 3‘ x. ‘ T. infill}! 2......‘0’ I.\¢.\.ol.... .331. an»: ‘ ll. ,Il THEOlS .‘\ I ”J 1" o F k” 22033/7/(005 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled AN ECONOMETRIC STUDY OF THE EFFECTS AND MOTIVATION FOR CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION IN PhD. TURKEY: 1993-2003 presented by PINAR OZBAY has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the degree in A ECONOMICS 2 r »- W Major Professor's Signature ngurl 1&a004 Date MSU is an Afinnative Action/Equal Opportunity Insfitufion . - ,.— --"‘-‘—.'_'. " _ .__._ 4 '- LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 cJCIRC/DateDuepes-sz AN ECONOMETRIC STUDY OF THE EFFECTS AND MOTIVATION FOR CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION IN TURKEY: 1993-2003 by Pinar Ozbay A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University In partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2004 ABSTRACT AN ECONOMETRIC STUDY OF THE EFFECTS AND MOTIVATION FOR CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION IN TURKEY: 1993-2003 by Pinar Ozbay This dissertation consists of four distinct chapters, all of which model and examine the effects and motivation of central bank intervention in Turkey during 1993-2003. Chapter one considers the effectiveness of central bank intervention in the Turkish Lira- US$ spot exchange rate market for different exchange rate policy regimes in Turkey. Forms of GARCH models are used to present the effect of intervention on both the mean and volatility process. Chapter two is concerned with the motivations of the central bank intervention in the Turkish Lira-US$ spot exchange market. The central bank intervention reaction function is modeled using probit, tobit and censored least absolute deviation models. Chapter three examines the intervention reaction function with a different approach. The Threshold model is used in the non-linear estimation of the reaction function in the Turkish Lira-USS spot exchange market. Chapter four is concerned with the relation between risk premium and central bank intervention. Forward rates are calculated for the Turkish Lira-US$ spot exchange market and then the effect of central bank intervention on risk premium is presented. Cepyright by PINAR OZBAY 2004 This dissertation is dedicated to my beloved husband, Gokce Ozlu, my mother, Hatice Ercan, my brother and my sister For their love, encouragement and trust iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Without the assistance and encouragement of many people, I could not have finished this work and present it in this form. First of all, my sincerest thanks goes to Professor Richard T. Baillie, my mentor. His technical and general advice made my dissertation possible. He gave me valuable comments and suggestions . His help and comments were invaluable. I owe a special thanks to Dr. Ana Maria Herrera. She gave me very helpful comments for my dissertation and helped me to complete it. I like to thank Dr. Thomas Jeitschko for his advice. He helped me to navigate the rough waters of the whole dissertation process. I also like to thank Artem Prokhorov and Jongbyung Jun for their advice and friendship. Especially Artem Prokhorov, who gave me great help in studying econometrics and the GAUSS programming language. The greatest thanks, however, goes to my lovely family. My beloved husband, Gokce Ozlu, has been a constant source of inspiration and encouragement. His dedication and support have been so great and helped move my dissertation forward. And my family have always supported and encouraged me in everything that I have done. Their love, patience and trust are things that I would never be able to repay. Thanks to all of them. Finally, I gratefully acknowledge support from the Central Bank of Turkey and the Department of Economics, Michigan State University. They provided me with the scholarship and helped motivate me to complete my dissertation. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................. viii LIST OF FIGURES .................................................................................... x CHAPTER 1. IS CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION EFFECTIVE? 1 .1 . Introduction ............................................................................... 1 1.2. Economic Developments in Turkey ................................................... 11 1.3. Data ...................................................................................... 32 1.4. Model and Estimation Output ........................................................ 43 1.5. Conclusion .............................................................................. 54 CHAPTER 2. WHAT MOTIVATES CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION? 2.1 . Introduction ............................................................................ 55 2.2. Modeling Intervention Behaviour ................................................... 57 2.3.1 Probit Model ......................................................................... 60 2.3.2 Estimation Results .................................................................... 63 2.4.1. Tobit and Censored Least Absolute Deviation Model ......................... 67 2.4.2. Estimation Output ................................................................... 69 2.5. Conclusion ............................................................................... 76 CHAPTER 3. THRESHOLD NON-LINEAR ESTIMATION OF THE CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION RACTION FUNCTION 3.1 . Introduction .............................................................................. 78 3.2. Estimation of Threshold Model ....................................................... 79 3.3 Tests for Nonlinearity and Estimation Output of Reaction Function ........... 86 vi 3.4. Conclusion ............................................................................. 98 CHAPTER 4. RISK PREMIUM AND CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTION 4. 1 . Introduction ............................................................................. 99 4.2. Details of the Model: Risk Premium and Intervention ......................... 101 4.3. Data .................................................................................... 104 4.4. Estimation Output .................................................................... 111 4.5. Conclusion ............................................................................ 114 CHAPTER 5. CONCLUSION ................................................................... 1 15 LIST OF REFERENCES ......................................................................... 118 vii LIST OF TABLES CHAPTER 1 Table 1.1: Main Economic Indicators ............................................................ 13 Table 1.2: Estimation of Intervention Model (1993-1999)......................................47 Table 1.3: Estimation of Intervention Model (1995-1999) .................................... 48 Table 1.4: Estimation of Intervention Model (2000-2003). ...................................... 52 Table 1.5: Estimation of Intervention Model (2001-2003). ........................................ 53 CHAPTER 2 Table 2.1: Estimation ofProbit Intervention Model (1995-1999). 64 Table 2.2: Estimation of Probit Intervention Model (2001-2003). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6........6 Table 2.3: Estimation of Tobit Intervention Model (1995-1999) ............................. 71 Table 2.4: Estimation of Censored LAD Intervention Model (1995-1999). . . . . . . . ...........72 Table 2.5: Estimation ofTobit Intervention Model (2001-2003). . . . . . . . ...74 Table 2.6: Estimation of Censored LAD Intervention Model (2001-2003) ................. 75 CHAPTER 3 Table 3.1: Test for Non-Linearity (1995-1999) ................................................. 87 Table 3.2: Estimation of Threshold Intervention Reaction Function (1995-1999) ........... 89 Table 3.3: Least Squares Estimation of Conditional Variance (1995-1999). . . . . . . . . ....90 Table 3.4: Test for Non-Linearity (2001-2003) ................................................. 92 Table 3.5: Estimation of Threshold Intervention Reaction Function (2001-2003) ........... 95 Table 3.6: Least Squares Estimation of Conditional Variance (2001-2003). . . . . . . . . ...96 viii CHAPTER 4 Table 4.1: Estimation of Intervention/ Risk Premium Model (1994-1999). . . . . . . . . .....1 12 Table 4.2: Estimation of Intervention/ Risk Premium Model (2001-2003). . . . . . . . . .....1 13 ix LIST OF FIGURES CHAPTER 1 Figure 1.1: Percentage Change in Annual GNP ................................................. 14 Figure 1.2: Inflation and Interest Rate .............................................................. 15 Figure 1.3: Spot Rate (TL/USD) (November 1993-1994) ....................................... 18 Figure 1.4: Overnight Interest Rates (November 1993-1994) .................................. 19 Figure 1.5: Spot Rate (TL/USD) (1995-1999) ................................................... 22 Figure 1.6: Spot Rate (TL/USD) (2000-2003) .................................................... 26 Figure 1.7: Overnight Interest Rates (J anuary-October 2000) ................................. 27 Figure 1.8: Overnight Interest Rates (March,2001-2003) ....................................... 28 Figure 1.9: Spot Return (TL/USD) (November 1993-2003) .................................. 34 Figure 1.10: Spot Return (TL/USD) (November 1993-1994) ................................. 35 Figure 1.11: Overnight Interest Rates (November 1993-1994)................................36 Figure 1.12: Spot Return (TL/USD) (1995-1999) ............................................... 37 Figure 1.13: Overnight Interest Rates (1995-1999) .............................................. 38 Figure 1.14: Spot Return (TL/USD) (2000-2003) ................................................ 40 Figure 1.15: Overnight Interest Rates (January, 2000-October 2000).... . ....41 Figure 1.16: Overnight Interest Rates (March, 2001-2003)........... . ...42 CHAPTER 4 Figure 4.1: Forward Exchange Rate (TL/USD) (1993-2002) ................................. 106 Figure 4.2: Spot Exchange Rate (TL/U SD) (1993-2002) ..................................... 107 Figure 4.3: Forward Rate Forecast Error (1994-1999) ........................................ 109 Figure 4.4: Forward Rate Forecast Error (2001-2003) ....................................... 110 CHAPTER 1 Is Central Bank Intervention Effective? 1.1 Introduction Exchange rate intervention in the foreign exchange market is defined as the buying and selling of foreign currency by a central bank or government in an attempt to influence the level of an exchange rate. There are two main motives of intervention. The first one is to influence the level of an exchange rate and the second one is to reduce its volatility or in other words to calm a disorderly market. Intervention is generally sterilized such that purchase (sale) of foreign currency is offset by a corresponding sale(purchase) of domestic government debt to eliminate the effect on the money supply. Hence intervention is quite distinct from pure monetary policy. Sterilized intervention provides monetary authorities to aim an exchange rate target objective independent of their monetary policy. Studies of intervention often distinguish between sterilized intervention, which does not affect the money supply, and non-sterilized intervention which does. Despite the agreement among economists about the effectiveness of non-sterilized intervention, the effect of sterilized intervention is much more controversial. Non-sterilized intervention is expected to directly affect the exchange rate because it changes the stock of base money and involves broader money aggregates, interest rates, real demands for goods and assets, and market expectations. Sterilized intervention leaves the monetary base unchanged. So it is not expected to affect the exchange rate through the monetary channel. In contrast to the direct effect, intervention, even if sterilized, can influence exchange rates through the portfolio and the signaling channels. Sterilized intervention will alter the relative supplies of domestic money and bonds. With risk averse investors who view domestic and foreign bonds a s imperfect s ubstitutes, the impact 0 f intervention will In ake them trade b onds which, in turn, will lead to an adjustment of the relative rate of return by changing the exchange rate. A sterilized purchase of foreign exchange increases the amount of publicly held domestic bonds, relative to foreign bonds, and induces a depreciation of the domestic currency. The portfolio balance theory implies there will be no impact of intervention on the exchange rate when there is perfect substitutability of bonds. To test this, theory requires information on the relative supplies of the assets. In the signaling channel, central banks try to influence exchange rates by conveying to the market a signal concerning current or future monetary or exchange rate policy. That is, sterilized purchases of foreign currency are expected to lead to a depreciation of the exchange rate if the foreign currency purchase is assumed to signal a more expansionary domestic monetary policy. This channel is largely acknowledged as the main path by which interventions affect foreign exchange markets. There is an enormous amount of literature concerning the effects of intervention on currency markets and the motivations for intervention. While researchers have been able to document short-lived effects, the overwhelming conclusion after studying the literature is that foreign exchange intervention is not effective for influencing the level and the volatility of the exchange rate. See Edison (1993), Almekinders (1995), Baillie et a1. (2000), Schwartz (2000), Samo and Taylor (2001), King (2003) and Humpage (2003). Empirical studies of the 19803 are characterized by two major handicaps, a lack of data on intervention and also a lack of survey data on exchange rate expectations. Studies on intervention in the 1990s and early 2000‘s use high quality daily data on intervention. Policy-makers seem to believe that it is possible for a central bank to significantly affect the supply and demand conditions in the foreign exchange market. In the 19803 and 199OS, attention focused on the effect of sterilized intervention on the level of the exchange rate and the channels through which intervention works. Humpage (1988) and Obstfeld (1989) note that the monetary amount of intervention is very small in comparison to the total market trading. Most empirical studies, such as Humpage (1988), Baillie and Osterberg (1997b) and Beine et a1 (2002) find a “leaning against the wind” phenomenon, which is regarded as economically unsatisfactory. Usually if any significant relationship is found, it is of the “leaning against the wind” type, with the Fed buying dollars associated with a subsequent dollar depreciation next period. This is almost certainly due to the policy endogeneity issue, with the bank buying dollars to support the already depreciating currency. There is general consensus in the literature that intervention does not affect exchange rates through the portfolio channel. Lewis (1988) estimates outside bond demand equations from the portfolio balance model of exchange rate determination for five currencies. The portfolio balance model focuses upon bonds fiom outside the economic sector that arise from the government debt. Different from the previous studies, she decomposes the foreign asset by currency. Despite improved empirical techniques, estimates of the portfolio balance model remain imprecise. Ghosh (1992) tested the portfolio balance channel for sterilized intervention by examining the effects of changes in relative asset supplies on the dollar-deutschmark rate during the 19805. A weak but significant portfolio balance influence is found. He concludes that substantial intervention is required to influence the exchange rate through portfolio balance effects. Dominquez and Frankel (1993b) estimate a portfolio balance equation that is consistent with mean-variance optimization. In this model, expected firture exchange rates are represented by data fi'om surveys of expectations among private exchange market expectations. Their main conclusion is that sterilized interventions are effective if they change the risk premium and that cumulative intervention has a statistically significant effect on the risk premium. Edison (1993) provides a comprehensive review of literature that focuses on empirical work conducted in the 19808. Most of the empirical evidence summarized in Edison‘s survey suggests that intervention can affect the exchange rate through the signaling channel but not the portfolio-balance channel. Almekinders (1995) agrees with Edison (1993) that no systematic effect of sterilized intervention via the portfolio balance channel is found in empirical evidence. Data limitations and theoretical and econometric problems have made it impossible to estimate the portfolio balance model and measure the effects of sterilized intervention satisfactorily. Only official exchange market operations, which c reate e xpectations o f c hanges in m onetary p olicy, o r w hich embody another sufficient ‘news’ content, appear to have a chance of affecting the exchange rate significantly. In their brief survey on recent literature, Samo and Taylor (2001) focus on the empirical work conducted in 19905. They suggest that the portfolio balance channel will diminish in importance over time, at least among the major industrialized countries, as capital markets become increasingly integrated and the degree of substitutability between financial assets increases. Most monetary authorities and economists believe that if intervention works, then it must be through the signalling or expectations channel. See Samo and Taylor (2001). The signaling channel assumes that intervention affects exchange rates by providing the market with new and relevant information to other market participants. In research on signaling, coordinated intervention is assumed to be more. effective than unilateral intervention. Despite the consensus among economists about the effectiveness of coordinated intervention, there is still a debate on whether or not the transparency of monetary authorities‘ actions and objectives is necessary. While some studies provide that secrecy is desired, others recommend that intervention be made public and the objectiveness made transparent in order to increase the effectiveness through the signaling channel. In a 1990 study, Dominquez discusses credibility games involving signaling and concludes that credible intervention signals, will be effective as the non- sterilized intervention when the central bank invokes its promised monetary policy. The study also implies that coordinated intervention may differ from unilateral intervention in terms of its impact on foreign exchange markets. Coordinated intervention has a significantly different and longer-term influence on market expectations than does unilateral intervention. Weekly data on monetary surprises, exchange rates and intervention is used and the effectiveness of intervention to vary with the credibility of monetary policy is found. Similar to Dominquez (1990), Humpage (1999) found that coordinated intervention increases the probability of success in affecting market expectations. The size of an intervention also affects its probability of success, but coordinated is generally a better predictor. He tested the hypothesis that the Federal Reserve routinely has better information concerning exchange rate movements than the market following the Louvre Accord. The frequency of success was relatively low, implying that the US interventions generally possessed little forecast value. However, there was evidence of intervention as a predictor that recent exchange rate movements would moderate, but not reverse. Coordinated and possibly the amount of intervention increased the probability of success. Samo and Taylor (2001) mention that official intervention can be effective through its role as a signal of policy intentions, especially when it is publicly announced and coordinated. Contrary to Dominquez (1990) and Humpage (1999), Vitale (1999) shows that when the uncertainty about the objective of foreign exchange intervention is particularly severe, the monetary authorities may target the exchange rate more successfully. The market is more efficient when this objective is secret than when it is common knowledge. Baillie, Humpage and Osterberg (2000) surveyed the literature on informational issues. They suggest researchers should carefully consider whether intervention might provide information to the market or whether the authorities have a clearer underaanding of market conditions than less informed private traders. Popper and Montgomery (2001) discuss that a central bank can affect the exchange rate by aggregating and disseminating agents‘ information. The intervention is a useful way to transmit this information. Most of the empirical studies show that sterilized interventions have little impact on the exchange rate. Fatum and Hutchison (2003) used an event-study approach to assess the effectiveness of intervention operations. In contrast to other studies, they found that official intervention is effective when directed to short-run objectives. An often stated objective of intervention policy is to cahn disorderly markets. Bonser- Neal and Tanner (1996), Baillie and Osterberg (1997b), Hung (1997), Chang and Taylor (1998), Dominquez (1998), Beine et a1 (2002) all find evidence that intervention tends to increase spot exchange rate volatility.Dominquez (1998) mentions that while intervention policy ofien influences exchange rate volatility, it is not volatility that causes intervention. A more surprising result is that secret interventions were generally found to increase volatility. This result provides evidence that the more ambiguous are signals, the more likely they are to increase volatility. Galati and Melick (1999) focused on intervention that is perceived by market participants, different from the actual interventions. Their analysis suggests that, on average, perceived intervention in support of the dollar fails to strengthen the currency. They find that market perceived intervention may increase the uncertainty prevailing in the market regarding future movements in the spot market. Besides these two effect, perceived intervention does not change the balance of weights that market participants assign to future sharp appreciations and sharp depreciations. There is empirical evidence which indicates that some types of intervention can affect the risk premia in forward markets. However, the risk premium is not necessarily the intended target of the intervention .Likewise, evidence that spot exchange rate volatility is frequently increased following intervention may be an unintentional extemality of intervention. Baillie and Osterberg (1997a) find that purchases of US dollars by the Federal Reserve appear to have significantly increased dollar denominated returns over uncovered interest rate parity for both the DM-$ and the Yen-S. However the effect is not symmetric since the Fed‘s actions has an impact, while the other central bank‘s actions do not. They also find some evidence that intervention leads to increases in volatility of the risk p remium, as w ell as a ffecting the c onditional m ean o f the risk premium. The nature of the causality appears unidirectional since there is no evidence that volatility of the forward premium Granger causes intervention. Consistent with this study, Baillie and Osterberg (2000) find some support for the intervention variables affecting the risk premium in the analysis where the relationship between daily deviations from uncovered interest rate parity and intervention is investigated by using daily overnight euro-currency deposit rates. Another area of investigation has been the relationship between central bank profits and intervention. Sweeney (1997) noted that if central banks have better information than the market, then they should consistently be able to earn profits on their intervention activity. Leahy (1995) and Neely (1998), Saacke(2002) had similar results. Kim and Sheen (2002) note that profitability is important in determining intervention like the other factors s uch a s, o vemight interest differentials, volatility smoothing and exchange rate trend correction. Following Samo and Taylor (2001), King (2003) and Humpage (2003) present a brief survey on the empirical work conducted post-1992. Similar to Sarno and Taylor (2001), Humpage (2003) mentions that if the transaction of the given intervention is large and coordinated, the probability to have the desired effect increases. He emphasizes the methodological problems of the estimation techniques and suggests that the timing issue with respect to the intervention data should be solved; otherwise empirical studies will give limited information about the efficacy of intervention. He suggests using high frequency and intra-day data, so that intervention appears to affect the exchange rate within minutes. Empirical studies using intra-day intervention data are available in the recent literature. See Dominquez (2003) and Chang and Taylor (1998). Dominquez (2003) used intra-day (5-minutes) intervention data on DM-USD and Yen-USD. She mentions that intervention operations, especially coordinated types, are consistently associated with increases in intra-day and daily volatility while there is little evidence that interventions influence longer-term volatility. Chang and Taylor (1998) also find similar results. King (2003) mentioned that empirical studies show that foreign exchange intervention has a transitory effect on the level or volatility of the exchange rate because foreign exchange intervention may be undertaken to meet a range of objectives and the studies do not adequately adress how these objectives may vary over time. The results on the effectiveness of intervention are mixed and depend on which exchange rate regime is analyzed, what sample period is studied and on the intervention strategy that is followed. Empirical studies are often done for the developed and big economies, yet few studies are available for developing and small economies. Hutchison (2003) discusses that coordinated intervention is desirable in the short-run stabilization policies of developing countries. Data on the amounts of intervention used by countries with their currencies in target, or managed exchange rate regimes are usually impossible to obtain and are regarded as highly secret, unlike the data on free-floating regimes. In this study, the effect of intervention is investigated in Turkey. It is a small economy that has had high inflation during the last 20 years. There is only one empirical study in recent literature with respect to F X intervention in Turkey. See Domac and Mendoza (2004). They find that interventions decreased the volatility of exchange rate during the free-float regime covering the period February 22, 2001 through May 30, 2002. This study used the data which covers the period November 1993 through December 2003. The Turkish economy had both managed and free float exchange rate regimes during this period. This enables us to make a comparison of the effect of intervention under different exchange rate regimes in a small-open economy with high inflation. Section 1.2 discusses the economic developments through the whole period 10 covered in this study. Sections 1.3 and 1.4 discuss the data, model and the estimation results. Finally Section 1.5 gives a brief conclusion. 1.2 Economic Developments Turkey adopted liberal economic policies in 19805 and financial liberalization brought important changes in the institutional arrangements of financial markets . Most trade liberalization was completed in the mid-19805 and Turkey entered into a customs union with the European Union in 1996. Similarly, the reforms in the financial area were also rapid and decisive. Interest rates were liberalized in the early 19805, residents were permitted to hold foreign exchange (FX) deposits in 1984. New institutional arrangements helped to develop money and bond markets in the late 19805, and capital movements and the exchange rate system were fully liberalized in August 1989. Despite the measures taken in the financial sector, public finance did not receive its proper share of reforms in the 19805. The economic environment was very unstable throughout the 19905 contrary to the developments throughout the 1980s. The financial crises, external shocks, high inflation, lack of fiscal disipline, the difficulty in the rollover of the growing domestic debt and political uncertainty were the main problems that created the unstable environment. Stabilization programs targeting price stability did not have political support, so efforts to decrease inflation were not successful. 11 The economic growth rate has been quite high except the crisis periods in 19905. Both the nominal rates of interest and inflation were very high almost throughout the decade of the 19905. See Table 1.1, Figure 1.1 and Figure 1.2. 12 4>m_.m in 2.9.: moose—an 52883 3° & 023 $3 33 3o“ 3: 3mm 38 $3 .38 $8 88 82 N8» MS“ 02.": i i M: E E 2 3 3 .3 $_ -3 A 29 53:83 2: u: 8E 32 8N u: 8... 8a 8m 82 $0 as. MS 533353] m: 8.0 mi 32 E a; :3 a; “3 8a 8... m3. n==oa>noocawma=8 No -2 .2 0.0 3 -.fi 2 02:1 me; ”@823 as S . mm 3 n5 SJOT 3mm} 3 g $— 3 m: as Ew— aa 3.... aa— moSoQ 08:2 5% 01:6 moccga a .3283 man 236 06358:. mama 59.83 a magmas 3 08mm zmaoag 38:2 623 03,5: mam 3 93% 5 253% o: :2: u as 1.5822 >58: >52QO acacia mma ...... 96:0 mmo§ acacia $358.83 a 3683 3 388m" 13 _ Hmmcwc HL" Hun-6939mm" Oran—mo m: >==:m_ 02W 7.\/ 3 L w _ _ ..7 3 . /\ / \ / > \ 7, .. . _ i < < rum H . /\/<\ L waa ubWu HOWN wau wah Hwem uwwa HOW.“ wam waw MAE: Nag: NQGN Ncau AJ 03% Zeno—5— 5.252 A023 m: 0.5.2: 5.38 14 L uni—=6 ab" main-ac: wan mane—den ”v.03 L _ um: um: . He: :! li||11-- ,- -,;|l-irli-aiilr,rl , -..Hac Ha: r-.iiii:.|:llg gull»; ,z1:;r - ,:- ii: use HNG 1 , we: r L a: V a: - L we . . _ i . . . . . _ _ . we H A use: Hem» Hews Heme Heem nee: nee» _ . i -- L L 7] I man—mac: I I JM—uncwcmn ”as D -- -lll- .. . .111 i .la .-.- - - i.iH..Iu|lrl. m .1 _ AJ 0.5.50 m: 363“.” noun—.52. $18 :58” A33 n 33 2:— >532. wanes?“ 5—8 15 The first half of the 19905’ were marked by the liberalization of capital movements in August 1989. Thereafter Turkish Lira (TL) appreciated continously in real terms except the two main depreciations. The first one occured in 1991, the year of the Gulf crisis, and the second one in 1994, the year Turkey experienced a severe financial crisis. Before the financial crisis, Turkey promoted exports by means of a real depreciation of TL . This policy changed after the crisis and Turkey promoted capital inflows by means of a real appreciation of TL. Public finances deteriorated markedly in 1992-1993 and political uncertainty intensified. Combined with an open capital account, this led to a financial crisis. The main factors were unsustainable fiscal policy, the strong desire to keep domestic interest rates below the market clearing levels, minimizing domestic debt finance and instead relying upon monetization. See Ozatay, (1994). Deterioration in fiscal balances and increased recourse to central bank financing, lack of fiscal discipline, and expansion of the credits extended to the public sector made it impossible for the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey (CBRT) to comply with the monetary program in 1993. Reliance on foreign debt and the CBRT advances increased by the end of 1993. The unsuitable environment for external borrowing necessitated financing of the deficit through central bank resources. At the same time domestic interest rates were administered such that the Treasury tried to pay less than the equilibrium interest rate on government securities and several Treasury auctions were cancelled. Moreover, an income tax on the holders of government bonds and bills was 16 introduced. The response of the private sector was not to purchase government securities and, therefore, a funding crisis started. Excess liquidity and bank’s high foreign exchange (FX) demand put upward pressure on the FX market. The turmoil in financial markets started in January 1994 and continued unabated through April, with the TL depreciating sharply on a daily basis, despite high interest rates and frequent interventions by the CBRT in the FX market. The US dollar appreciated by almost 70 percent in the first three months of 1994 against the TL. To prevent a further depreciation of the domestic currency, the CBRT increased the overnight interest rates and intervened both in the interbank money market and foreign exchange market. CBRT lost more than half of its international reserves whereas the interbank money market rates increased to record levels. The actions of the CBRT to stabilize the markets through open market operations proved insufficient and the rapid loss of reserves on a continuous basis called for more radical and widespread measures. The first devaluation was in January and the second one was in April. See Figures 1.3 and 1.4. On April 5, when the CBRT stopped intervening, the T L w as d evalued and the foreign e xchange m arket w as u nstable until May 1994. International agencies decreased the rating of Turkey’s government debt and three small b anks went bankrupt. H ence, the T urkish e conomy found itself i n a v ery severe financial crisis. 17 « A 4 3:223: AJ Gem—w. mac» ”one on Hiram—V man—.amam me: .512. o». a 236572.. 58 93.5.. w: 532.52.. 5: l8 A3 Hymn—=6 FA" 0.53.55!» Mano-6mg ”mace wGQ QGG _. .8: mac L ace _ we: we: _ :5 Nut-94 . m M H mm w W. W M W: Ibo-94 AJ Dam—w. Cad—.3“... Ego—.8" ”was mun—Eu?“ ...:— ualca on n 232.52.. 33 33:“.— ue Gena—Ban... Sea 19 The CBRT promulgated several new regulations regarding financial markets, and a new monetary framework was prepared in line with the IMF stand-by agreement afler the crisis. In the medium term, in order to achieve price stability, a tight monetary policy was put into effect. As stability reemerged in the markets, the treasury started to borrow from the domestic markets. Foreign reserves rose strongly in the second half of 1994. The second half of the 19905 was marked by monetary programs aiming at achieving stability in the financial markets. High inflation and an increase in the Public Sector Borrowing Requirement (PSBR) kept the interest rates high during 1995-1999. Economic growth was very strong except in 1999. The economy was characterized by high growth rates and high inflation in this period. Following this strong demand-led growth, a sharp decline was seen in 1999 due to the adverse effects of the earthquake in Turkey and the Russian banking crisis. See Table 1.1. The CBRT followed a monetary policy which focused on stabilizing the financial markets during 1995-1999. The CBRT announced publicly that its aim was to keep real exchange rates stable. This aimed both at affecting agents‘ inflationary expectations and to reducing the degree of uncertainty about the future of the economy. Under the constraints of an open capital account, large fiscal deficits and inertial inflation, CBRT aimed at maintaining financial market stability, which meant safeguarding competitiveness and minimizing the burden imposed by high fiscal borrowing requirements 0 n the financial sy stern. C BRT h as p repared a m onetary p rograrn e very 20 year since 1996. Although the programs were formulated with a certain inflation target in mind, this did not quite mean that reducing inflation was the key objective. Instead the overriding objective was real exchange rate stability and, ultimately, FX reserve strength. According to the standby agreement signed by IMF in early 1995, the exchange rate policy was based on the idea of utilizing exchange rates as a nominal anchor in curbing inflation. The increase in the foreign exchange basket, defined as 1.5 German marks and 1 US dollar, was targeted to increase by as much as the targeted monthly inflation rates. The basket was revised as 1 US dollar and 0.77 Euro by the introduction of Euro in 1999. Deviations from the targeted inflation rate were seen in certain periods and the targets for the basket were adjusted accordingly. During the managed float exchange rate policy, most of the sales of US dollar were seen in the last quarter of the year. The bank’s demand for foreign currency to close FX open positions put upward pressure on FX markets. CBRT sold US dollars usually when the German mark/US dollar parity rose, to achieve targets for the foreign exchange basket, excess liquidity, speculative increase in FX demand due to adverse effects of external crises like Russian and Argentine crises, an earthquake, and deterioration of expectations about Treasury’s domestic debt finance. When there was stability in the markets and capital inflow, or when the inflationary expectations decreased, CBRT usually bought US dollars and the reserves increased. 21 a 1 -151,1.1515151-- 51:51 .- 1|- fimm—unc PM" mvcn ”an AHFam—VVAJ WQHeeec . _ _ _ mucccc _ _s_eeee . unease . N H :25 1 1 l l _ L “Hueeee W Heeee M 3:335:33 AJ Gum—w. moon ”:3 on dram—v man—.535 =3 3: ~512— on N 55:93.. Sou «Sega—— 3 508552.. 58. 22 The economic environment was not good despite the stabilization efforts. Towards the end of the 19905, deterioration in public finances, high levels of real interest rates and inflation and the economic contraction necessiated the government to put a new medium term program into affect in 2000. The Turkish government adopted a disinflation program backed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) at the beginning of 2000. This program aimed at decreasing the inflation rate to single digits by the end of 2002 and had three main specific targets. First, it imposed limits on CBRT’s balance sheet items such that it limited monetary expansion only to changes in its net foreign asset position in the balance sheet. The CBRT committed itself to a policy of no sterilization. Changes in monetary base would be directly reflected changes in the net foreign assets of its balance sheet. CBRT‘s liquidity creation was tied to foreign capital inflows. Within this framework, the banks were sellers or buyers in the foreign exchange markets by considering increases in the short-term interest rates. Second, pre-announced target values of the currency basket, in other words a pre-announced calendar for the depreciation rate in line with the targeted inflation, were applied. Third, there were specific targets for primary surplus to ease the domestic debt finance. The CBRT confirmed that the exchange rate targets had been met by the end of 2000. The disappearance of the foreign exchange risk caused nominal interest rates to decline sharply. These developments in foreign exchange and interest rates led the consumption of durable goods, production, investment expenditures, credits and imports to rise and the Turkish economy, which had slowed down in 1998 and contracted in 23 1999, to enter a new period of growth in 2000. The monetary policy within the framework of the “Disinflation Program’ ’ was carried out until February 2001. The armounced increases in the basket at the beginning of the program were according to the targeted but below the realized inflation rates. The decreases in nominal interest rates were very sharp. This structure caused a deep deterioration in comparative advantage and so the current account balance. Delays in the implementation of structural reforms in the second half of 2000, and deviations from the privatization targets caused loss of credibility of the program enhancing devaluation expectations. In line with the monetary policy framework in which the CBRT’s liquidity creation was tied to foreign capital inflows, the increasing capital outflows, due to devaluation expectations, resulted in a rise in interbank money market interest rates in November 2000. Rising interest rates caused deterioration in the financial situation of banks with maturity mismatches in their balance sheets, causing a lack of confidence in the banking system. The financial system’s increasingly growing liquidity needs turned into financial crisis and the CBRT was left with no choice but to raise the liquidity it provided to the market. This situation brought about a departure from the targets determined for the CBRT’s balance sheet aggregates. Despite the fact that the crisis environment had been relatively subdued, the maturity of both domestic and external funds lessened because of the rapid rise in the risk premium, while the interest rates continued to stay at high levels relative to the currency basket’s rate of crawl. Following the political turmoil on February 19, 2001, prior to the Treasury’s auction, 3 great demand for foreign exchange emerged in the financial markets, but the CBRT tried to avoid the realization of the foreign exchange demand by 24 constraining the liquidity. This situation, however, resulted in a breakdown of the payments system due to the need of state banks for excessive overnight liquidity. The floating exchange rate regime was adopted on February 22, 2001 when the exchange rate policy had become unsustainable under existing circumstances. A sudden capital outflow caused a speculative attack on the foreign exchange market and, following the 22nd of February, a new exchange rate system was put into effect. See Figures 1.6 and 1.7 and 1.8. 25 mam—=6 Faumficn ”can Afifiam—VVE Neccccc Hmccccc 5;. Hmcccac unacccc Huccccc -. Haccccc acaccc 1- maaccc bccaca 3:333:33 AJ Cam—u. ween 5.8 on dram—v man—5E.“ :5 E: .5..ch c.- u SEE—J; N25 33:”: n: bane—ace... N98. 26 ‘+ \‘ -' I .111- .:-i ‘rjllli# A mam—:6 uh" 053.3%: 5.83m» ””263 :5 «a - , 15:5: ,;.14, 11 ---1, -, — NHL. .17L3T z- .3 i . E ¢ I 3 Sill! - _ _ . _ .3 4 .l 5111 1L1 _ _ _ AW? a W W W. W, W ( W W W W W Jun-00 ~ Jul-00 + WWW W |l.||lntull|'|.v |WIIL AJ Dam—w. 0:35.: nus—.8» 5:8 man—5E5 :5 E: .512— 3. u has-5Q. N25 33:»: um Cane—van. ~25. 27 mam—:6 Fm "Cad—fiat" Han—.8” ””383 :c :5 - ilii--,-i il i ,- l| ii: -, iii-i-,i-.. E. ii. .-i; , i -4 ,‘il--- i ii , iii , l Willi ac .j E llil: i ii iliii - i i i #6 iii 1 1 {iii ii- i, i iii i lliii- a: i fll‘lrr . --i -. 1 ma - i ,- --ii N: WW W WWWW AJ Dam—w 053mm... 58.63 5:8 man—5:5“ =5 ...... .512— 3. u 32.2.. ~8— Snccmw 3 58352.. 38. 28 The banking sector problem in Turkey was basically a result of the mechanism chosen to finance the very high public sector borrowing requirement. Firstly this led to an increase in government debt instruments in the balance sheets of private banks and caused a significant deterioration in state-owned banks because of their accumulating duty losses. There are two major interest-earning assets in the Turkish banking system- commercial loans and government debt instruments. The share of the government debt instruments portfolio in private commercial bank balance sheets was greater than the loan portfolio. See Ozatay and Sak (2001). The quality of the government instruments portfolio is directly related with the expectations regarding debt sustainability. This feature increased the vulnerability of the banking system to concerns about the rollover of the outstanding government debt instruments. Yeldan (2001) argues the Turkish currency crisis did not originate due to the failure of fiscal and monetary authorities in following the main targets of the program. The crisis conditions emerged as a result of the increased fragility in the financial system. Factors such as weak prudential regulation over the banking sector and finance of the large persistent fiscal deficits were instrumental in the burst of the crisis. Ozatay and Sak (2002) agree with him that a fragile banking system was the root cause of the crisis. The banking system was highly vulnerable to capital outflows. The foreign exchange risk was high in the period preceding the crisis. While the total open foreign exchange position of the banking system was increasing, the ratio of liquid foreign exchange denominated assets to total foreign exchange denominated liabilities was decreasing. Maturity mismatch was an other problem. The liabilities were more of a short-term nature while 29 the maturities of assets were longer. Also the share of the bad loans to total loans was very high. The new program put into effect after the crisis aimed mainly at arranging the role of the state banks and reducing their extensive short-term liabilities. The CBRT played a key role in the operation of restructuring the state banks. The CBRT set its short-term priorities so as to remove defects in the payments system, to make the financial system function again and to provide stability in financial markets. To avoid the inflationary effects, CBRT controlled base money by the implementation of monetary targeting. Moreover, considering the absence of a nominal anchor due to the abandoning of the exchange rate regime, money base targets were set to help the economic agents shape their expectations after switch to a free float regime. Short-term interest rates became the most important monetary policy tool in dealing with liquidity control and inflationary pressures during this period. The exchange rate depreciated substantially and was volatile after the switch to the floating rate regime. In the beginning of the floating exchange rate regime, the CBRT declared that the exchange rate would be determined by market dynamics. The FX interventions of the CBRT after the switch to the floating exchange rate regime was directed towards damping the excessive volatility in the FX level without affecting its long-run value. Moreover, a programmed auction system for FX sales was implemented as of March 29, 2001. FX sales auctions were conducted daily until May 17, 2001. Between May 17, 2001 and July 11, 2001, FX sales auctions conducted whenever 3O required without pre-announcing the amount. After July 11, 2001 the monthly program of FX sales auctions was pre-announced. These auctions were conducted in order to sterilize the excess liquidity in the market caused by the use of the external financing which was provided by the IMF to make the Treasury’s domestic debt payments. The CBRT sometimes intervened in the exchange rate markets in order to smooth the fluctuations which emerged in the case of negative external developments and domestic political problems. However, beginning in August, non-programmed interventions were reduced to negligible levels, and as of September, program based auctions were carried out on the daily basis. After November 30, 2001, FX sales auctions were conducted when they are required. The CBRT pursued foreign exchange buying auctions in order to absorb the excess supply of foreign exchange that was accumulated by reverse currency substitution and the surplus in the balance of payments in the first half of the 2002. These operations did not aim at distorting the long-run trend in exchange rates. Moreover, the CBRT did not try to establish any specific exchange rate level. Foreign exchange auctions were temporarily suspended as of July due to the volatilities of exchange rates, which occurred as a result of an increase in the perception of political uncertainty. Similar to 2002, in 2003 the CBRT intervened in the foreign exchange markets when there was high volatility and the operations did not aim to distort the long-run trend in exchange rates. Turkish economy was quite unstable through 19903. Because of the two financial crisis in 19905, it was realized that, without structural reforms, disinflation programs 31 ll have no chance to decrease the inflation so priority was given to structural reforms regarding the arrangements of economic institutions at the beginnings of 2000s and disinflation program has found more support after the crisis. Tight monetary and fiscal policies helped to achieve financial stability, which created a suitable environment for economic growth. 1.3 Data In this study, the data is provided by the CBRT. The data sample consists of both daily spot bid rates, interbank overnight interest rates and daily intervention variables from November 1993 through December 2003. Intervention values are in millions of US dollars. Exchange rate policies are different throughout the period. The analysis has been done separately for managed float and free float exchange rate policy regimes, respectively, including and excluding the crisis periods. So we take several sub-samples of the d ata. T he first 5 ub-sample h as the d aily amount 0 f 11 et d ollar p urchases (sales), daily spot bid rates and interest rates date from November 1993 through December 1999. This sub-sample covers the first financial crisis in April 1994 and exchange rate policy was managed float. Then the crisis period is excluded and only the period 1995-1999 is analyzed. This enables us to investigate the effect of intervention in both a crisis environment and without it. T he third sub-sample d ates from 2 000 through D ecember 2003. This period covers both crawling peg and free float regimes and include the second financial crisis. Then we exclude the financial crisis and estimate only the free float regime from February 27, 2001 through 2003. The daily spot returns for whole period is shown in Figure 1.9. The graphs of the spot returns and interest rates are drawn for 32 certain sub-samples in order to show the data better. The first sub-period consists of November 1993-1994 at which time exchange rate policy was managed float. In this period the first financial crisis happened. Daily spot returns and short-term interest rates are seen in Figures 1.10 and 1.11. The period 1995-1999 is marked by IMF- standby agreements. Exchange rate policy was managed float and the exchange rate basket was pegged to forecast inflation. Daily spot returns and short-term interest rates are seen in Figures 1.12 and 1.13. 33 a: we - i ili l i m N Nov-93 Nov-94 i Nov-95 i Nov-99 Nov-00 Nov-01 Nov-02 AJ 6:3. mi: ”25.: en dram—v mun—5:3” :5 E: 1012. 2. N 2363—5... new... 2.3.5.. 3 Ugo—Baa... 33. 34 mam—=6 PS" mug ”3:35 $55253 , um __ .3 _ ii -.i iii ail; _ I i 3 iii [ 5i _ i M _ _ .. \__>.,.i -m-i, 1 _ -3 I i Lm M M. M M M M M. M. m M M. m M M. 3 Us”? mg» ”02:... on dram—u mun—5:5 :5 E: .312— 3 N 238552.. 33 33:»: mo Dona—awn... 33. 35 mac .25 ac: mac £6: Mac Na: :5 AJ Dam—v. C5355 3:26.: 5:8 man—.5?" E: .512— 3. — 235552.. 33 93:“.— uc 582—52.. 5: 36 mam—=6 HAN“ m—x: ”2:35 AHFEmUVS . . .. i i - , ..1 iii i “ N L i ii - _ i - i i ii M H p — p -—-i b _ _. , m .— _ i - - . bit: I- i I I Iiii ». 1 ii I . TM ‘ AMZMMZMMZMMMMMMMMMMM mmMmmMMmmmMmmmMmmMMm. AJ 59:! mean ”25.: a. dram—u mun—~53" :8 3:12.25 3. N .35:qu 5cm 93.5.. 3 5325—3... 58. 37 Hui—=6 rum" 048-5539 7:9.an ”means Mm: NGG +l||€+eisr; :s- : . ‘i;:‘\“-! # .mc 11.? ix u :51 m6 1 fl .. :MZWZZMZEZWZ L—..__ .__.__~_ _._.—... ___~.. ._w.—_ 3593 0335—: man—.8" 5:8 man—5:5“ :5 E: “512. on N amass. Gem ...—.25: 3 528532.. 53. 38 The CBRT changed the exchange rate policy and adopted crawling peg regime in 2000. However, this policy was not sustainable afier the second financial crisis and free float regime is adopted in 2001. Daily spot returns, and short-term interest rates are seen in Figures 1.14 and 1.15, 1.16. During the crisis period interest rates increased to very high levels. It is difficult to show interest rates in one graph so we separate the period and graph the interest rates as before and afier crisis. 39 It lvillliil) _ Haw—5.0 HLAu maven Won—=5 AH‘FEWUVAJ _ _ a: n s Na ., --- ill ,4, llli- AJ Cum—v. mac. ”SE... 3. dram—v man—5:5“ :5 E: .512. on u ass—SQ. ~25 93:“: M: 58253... 33. 4O :5 m5 a: m: as w: H: wmmwww mm m N do Dun—w. 033—5.: min—.8. 5:8 man—5:3” 9a ...... 12.3.. on u SEE—Q. Nee: 933m.— .3 Cane—.0... was. 41 mam—=6 HLQOJGHBmm—un Mano—6m» Enema; . _ . . ‘ iii ‘ l I‘ .IliL a .s a ll Will, :IWWWI‘JJJJ q 4 a a a a d _ Jl a a 3:333:33 diva—vs GEE—mug man—.8. 258m man—5:5“ =5 «5:312. en a 326... N93 Ewosmr 3 6305—5... 38. 42 1.4 Model and Estimation Output In this section, we aim to test the direct effect of intervention on the level and volatility of spot returns. In the literature, there is mixed evidence about the effectiveness of intervention. 80 this analysis is a contribution to the literature such that we are able to analyse the effect of intervention in Turkey. Turkish economy is a small economy where the central bank is an important player in the foreign exchange market. So we expect the foreign exchange intervention to be effective. Also, this study enables us to investigate the effect of intervention under different exchange rate policy regimes and crisis environment. Intervention is proposed to affect the mean and volatility of the spot rate. The model in this study is built around the standard Martingale model with time dependent conditional heteroscedasticity. Following Bollerslev (1986) and Baillie and Bollerslev (1989), the conditional variance is modeled as a linear Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (GARCH) process (see equation 1.3). Bollerslev (1986) introduced the GARCH (1,1) process, which extends the ARCH model to make 0,2 a function of lagged values of 0,2 as well as the lagged values of 8,2 Bollerslev (1986) required all the coefficients to be positive to ensure that the conditional variance is n ever negative. The q uasi- m aximum likelihood e stimation is u sed. In this study, the aim is to investigate the effect of central bank intervention on the foreign exchange markets. We used a linear GARCH (1,1) model following Baillie and Osterberg ( 1997b) . 43 4 n b . . AlnSt = b0 +b1USt_2 +b2US,_25 +b3z,_2 +'21di +2111. +5, (1.1) l: where A In S, =100[In(St)— In (s,_1 )] a,=z,a, with z, is iid (0,1) (1.2) 0,2 = a) + aat_12 + ,60',_12 + leSt_2b + 72USt_ZS (1.3) S is the level of the spot exchange rate in terms of the number of TL per one USS. l The variable AlnS: is the return on the exchange rate between 15.30 pm on day H and 15.30 pm on day t. The explanatory variables includes the intervention variables and short term interest rates, d, corresponds to the daily dummies and j, corresponds to the crisis dummies. Crisis dummies are used in the conditional mean to take control of the devaluations during the crisis period. j] and j 2 corresponds to the dummies to take control for the devaluations in January 1994 and April 1994, respectively, while j3 and L; corresponds to the dummies to take control for the following two days after the devaluation on April,5 1994. The intervention variables US b and US ‘ are purchases and sales of US dollars. Empirical results of estimating this model have generally been poor, probably because of the policy endogeneity issue, where a purchase of $ is found to be associated with a $ depreciation due to “leaning against the wind” phenomenon. See Baillie and Osterberg (1997) and Humpage (1988). The intervention variables are lagged to ensure they are 44 pre-determined to a avoid the possible simultaneity bias. The intervention variables are the logarithms of net purchases or sales of intervention ending at the close of the markets on day t-2. If no intervention occurs, then the intervention variable is set to zero. The short-term interest rate (i) is also lagged as t-2 and is the logarithm of (1+ f—gé) where on, is the overnight interest rate. The empirical results of the estimated models are given in Table 1.2 and Table 1.5. Asymptotic standard errors are in the second column with the corresponding parameter estimates. The statistics m3 and m 4 are the sample skewness and kurtosis of the standardized residuals. Q20 and Q202 are the Ljung-Box test statistics for autocorrelation and ARCH effects, and T is the sample size. The model is estimated for different sub-periods. First, the managed float period including the financial crisis, covers November 1993 through December 1999. The estimation output is shown in the Table 1.2.During the managed float period, intervention is sterilized and Emir et al (2000) showed that there was a low degree 0 f sterilization before the 1994 financial crisis and a high degree of sterilization during 1995-1999. The crisis dummy variables in the mean equation are statistically significant and their magnitude is large. There is also a significant Monday effect and this is most likely due to the calculation of daily target values for the basket according to the projected inflation in a m anaged float regime. T he p rojected m onthly increase in the b asket is linearized through the whole month, including the weekends, so the change between Friday and Monday includes target values for Saturday and Sunday as well. Also, most of the announcements w ere (1 one towards o r o n the w eekends w hen the m arkets are closed. 45 Most of the responses to the news are reflected on Monday when the markets are open. The most important finding regarding to results for managed float period is that intervention h as b een unable to influence the c hange in the exchange rate. D uring the managed float regime, the aim is to achieve the targets for the basket which consists of US dollar and German mark (euro after 1999). After the crisis, the turmoil in financial markets continued unabated through several months, with the TL depreciating sharply on a daily basis, despite high interest rates and frequent interventions by the CBRT in the F X market. The empirical results suggests that the short term interest rate has been able to influence the exchange rate such that increase in interest rates appreciates the US dollar. A 2002 study by Gumus supports our findings as it reports that raising interest rates had a significant effect on depreciating the nominal exchange rates. There is persistent volatility in the conditional variance. The sum of the coefficients of squared residual and the lagged value of variance is close to 1. The kurtosis of the standardized residuals is high. Skewness is also high and positive. There is also evidence that intervention have no effect on the volatility of the daily spot returns. During this period CBRT aimed at reducing the volatility in real exchange rates. 46 Table 1.2: Estimation of Intervention Mode Conditional Mean Parameters l (a) (I) a 13 "Yr 'Yz Skewness Kurtosis on2 020 '1‘ 0.2877 0.3249 0.0198 0.0220 0.0327 12.2960 " 35.8032 25.2516 43.3175 ° Conditional Variance Parameters 0.0208 0.2192 0.7214 -0.0021 -0.0019 Coefiicient -0.0049 -0.0003 -0.0062 .0. .0. Standard Error 1.34 17.55 30.76 15.28 1558 0.0842 0.0070 0.0070 0.1630 0.03 86 0.0291 0.0346 0.0310 0.2430 2.6724 2.61 18 2.8799 0.0092 0.0687 0.0865 0.0019 0.0019 1" Full period of 1 November, 1993 through 31 December, 1999. (‘0 denotes 10% significance level ('1') denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level AlnSt =b0 +b1US,_2b +b2USt—ZS +b3i,_ 2 2+. 1 at = a) +a8t_12 + 60,42 + 71US1_2b + yzUSt_23 5t =21“: 47 with z, is iid (0,1) 4 n 2 di +2 ji +8, =1 i=1 Table 1.3: Estimation of Intervention Model ‘a’ Conditional Mean Parameters Coefficent Standard Error b0 -0.0555 0.0753 bl 0.0007 0.0061 b; -0.0035 0.0063 b, 0.3884 0.1375 d1 0.3267 0.0332 d2 0.0022 0.0257 113 0.0039 0.0278 d4 0.0028 0.0274 Conditional Variance Parameters to 0.0134 0.0045 01 0.1641 ” 0.0675 [3 0.7267 0.0635 7, 0.0002 0.0012 72 0.0001 0.0013 Skewness 0.48 Kurtosis 9.92 Q20 31.86 onz 15.02 T 1259 ('0 Full period of 1 November, 1993 through 31 December, 1999. (*) denotes 10% significance level 0") denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level 4 n ' 2 +§1di+i§11i+£t AlnS, =00 +b1USt_2b +02US,_25 +b3it_ I 0,2 = a) + (16,42 + flat_12 +y1USt_2b + 72USt_23 5t=zt0t with Zt is iid (0,1) 48 The intervention models were also estimated for the period 1995-1999, which excludes the crisis period. The empirical findings shown in Table 1.3 for period 1995- 1999 are similar to the results for 1993-1999. Intervention has been unable to influence the change in the exchange rate. The signs are as expected but not significant and there is a significant Monday effect. Overnight interest rates are significant but not of the expected sign. There is a tendency that the increase in o vemight rates is a ssociated with a subsequent d ollar appreciation. D uring this period inflation is high and agents have inflationary expectations. They already know that the US dollar will appreciate as long as inflation is high. The basket which consists of the US dollar and TL is pegged to inflation. High interest rates indicate high inflation and result in a strong FX demand. The intervention variables have no effect on the volatility during this period. The empirical results of the models estimated for the period 2000 through 2003 are quite different from the models for the m anaged float regime. During the D isinflation Program covering the period January 1, 2000-February 21, 2001, intervention is not sterilized but after a switch to a fi'ee float regime, intervention is fully sterilized. This period includes the second financial crisis. The empirical results are shown in Table 1.4. Linear integrated GARCH (1,1) model is estimated. The coefficients of intervention are significant. Purchases of US dollars are associated with subsequent dollar appreciation. This is most probably due to that the central bank intervenes (purchases) with the wind during the crawling peg period. Sales of US dollars is followed by the appreciation of the US dollar. This effect is sometimes known as the leaning against the wind phenomenon 49 and suggests the possibility of policy endogeneity with central banks selling dollars because the dollar is appreciating. The TL depreciated substantially and displayed a highly volatile pattern in the first months after the switch to the free float regime. The CBRT conducted regular FX sales auctions to smooth excessive short-run exchange rate fluctuations without affecting the long-run equilibrium level of exchange rates and to perform FX sales in a more transparent manner in the first half of 2001. Contrary to a managed float period, increase in interest rates decrease the spot returns as expected. The crisis dummies are also statistically significant. jl corresponds to the devaluation day, February 22, 2001 and j2 and j3 corresponds to the following two days after the crisis, respectively. We exclude the crisis period and estimate the same models for the free float period for February 27, 2001 through December 31, 2003. The empirical findings are shown in Table 1.5. After the switch to a free float regime, CBRT declared that the exchange rate would be determined by market dynamics and it would not intervene in the exchange rate markets except in cases where the exchange rate displayed an instantaneous and highly volatile pattern. Intervention is fiilly sterilized and, more importantly, announced to the market. The empirical findings for the free float regime have similarities with the ones for managed float regime. Intervention has been unable to influence the change in exchange returns. Contrary to Domac and Mendoza (2004), although the central bank advocated the use of intervention to reduce exchange rate volatility, sales of US dollars may have actually Granger caused an increase in volatility and this result may reflect that intervention, by providing more information to market participants, which can induce 50 increased volatility as agents adjust their positions. Similar to intervention, overnight interest rates are also not effective during this period. The sign is as expected but not significant. 51 Table 1.4: Estimation of Intervention Model 0" Conditional Mean Parameters Coefficient Standard Error b0 -0.0694 0.0723 bl 0.0390 0.0112 b2 0.0306 0.0111 b3 -0.2900 ” 0.1238 11, 0.1804 0.0544 d2 0.0940 0.0603 113 0.1400 ” 0.0573 d4 0.0990 ’ 0.0569 j1 33.0800 0.8556 j2 10.9346 1.0750 j; 43.9610 1.1828 Conditional Variance Parameters to 0.0288 " 0.0183 [3 0.2115 ‘ 0.0954 7, -0.0055 0.0034 72 -0.0031 0.0028 Skewness 0.608 Kurtosis 5.538 Q20 32.68 onz 26.98 T 1004 (a) Full period of 1 November, 1993 through 31 December, 1999. (*) denotes 10% significance level ('1') denotes 5% significance level 1*") denotes 1% significance level 4 n_ 2di+Zji+5t ' i=1 AlnSt =b0 +b1US¢_2b mgr/5,45 +b3it_ 1 1: 2+ O'tz = a) +a8t_12 +fl0't_12 +}’1US1_2b +72USt_28 8t=2t0t With zt is iid (0,1) 52 Table 1.5: Estimation of Intervention Model (”0 Conditional Mean Parameters Coefficent Standard Error b0 -O.2198 0.1987 bl 0.0202 0.0203 b, 0.0295 0.0497 b, 0.0998 0.5049 d1 0.1878” 0.0371 d2 0.104 0.1071 6, 0.2094“ 0.104 d4 0.0768 0.0962 Conditional Variance Parameters to 00834 0.0397 01 0.2954” 0.1 133 p 0.6105‘” 0.1129 7, 0.0019 0.0097 72 0-192" 0.0838 Skewness 0.9 Kurtosis 5.26 Q20 29.4 Q202 15.1 1 T 712 ('0 Full period or 1 November, 1993 through 31 December, 1999. 0’) denotes 10% significance level (...) denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level 4 n 2 +§1di +311}. +8, AlnS, =b0 +b1USt_2b +b2US,_2‘ +b3it_ 1_ 0’2 = a) +a£t_12 +fl0't_12 +71USt_2b +72USt_2S €t=ZtUt With zt is iid (0,1) 1.5 Conclusion In this section we investigated the effect of intervention on both the level and volatility of spot returns in Turkey. The analysis covers the period November 1, 1993- December 31, 2003. It is a common belief among policy-makers that central bank intervention is effective. However, the evidence on the effectiveness of intervention is mixed. In general, the evidence is disposed towards ineffectiveness. We also find evidence that central bank intervention was not effective in Turkish foreign exchange market during the period November 1, 1993-December 31, 2003. We estimate a linear GARCH ( 1,1) model for different sub-periods including and excluding the crisis periods. The results show that intervention has been unable to affect the level of spot returns both in managed and flee float regimes except during the sub-period January 1, 2000-February 21, 2001. While intervention has no effect on volatility in managed float regime, it increases the volatility in a flee float regime. With respect to effect of short-term interest rate, an increase in overnight interest rates appreciates US dollar in a managed float regime but has no effect in a flee float regime. 54 CHAPTER 2 What Motivates Central Bank Intervention? 2.1. Introduction In the first chapter, we find evidence that central bank intervention was not effective in Turkish foreign exchange market during the period November 1993-December 2003. In this chapter we ask the question what motivates central bank intervention and analyze the estimation of intervention reaction fimction. A proposed relationship between the amounts of intervention and the various characteristics of a disorderly foreign exchange market is called a reaction function. Since no specific measures of the disorderly market conditions are given by either the central banks or by economic theories, economists often rely on econometric methodologies to test if certain characteristics of the market are closely related to the interventions. One of the main challenges in specifying a reaction function is the fact that the intervention variable has a zero value for the majority of the observations in a sample while the explanatory variables are not zero. This implies a non-linear relationship because the observed quantities of intervention do not increase or decrease approximately in proportion to the level of the explanatory variables. One way to proceed is to approximate this potential non-linear relationship with a linear model. Eij ffinger and 55 Gruijters (1991), Ito (2002), Rogers and Siklos (2003) used simple OLS models. An other way is to model the probability, rather than the quantity of intervention, uses a probit approach, as in Baillie and Osterberg (1997), Dominquez (1998), Kim and Sheen (2002) and McKenzie (2004). Recent studies use ordered probit as in F renkel, Pierdzioch and Stadtrnann (2003), and Ito and Yabu (2004). Different flom the probit model, Frenkel and Stadtrnann (2001) use the logit model. If one is interested in the quantity, rather than the probability of intervention, an appropriate model may be a Tobit model. Almekinders and Eij ffinger (1994) and Humpage (1999) follow this approach. However, a Tobit approach takes either a buying intervention or a selling intervention one at a time but not both as the dependent variable. If one wants to explain both types of intervention simultaneously , then the fliction model may be an appropriate specification for the reaction function as in Almekinders and Eijffinger (1996), Kim and Sheen (2002) and Sheen (2002). In the first chapter we estimate the effect of intervention on the spot returns using linear GARCH(1,1) model for different sub-samples including and excluding the crisis period. In this chapter, we only take the sub-samples of managed float and flee float period excluding the crisis period. During the crisis period, the motivations for intervention may be quite different flom normal times. We first used the probit model to assess the probability of intervention. We then use a tobit model and compared the results and found that the main assumptions of the tobit model of homoscedasticity and normality are likely to be invalid. Hence we used the censored least absolute deviation method, as suggested by Powell (1984) to get asymtotically consistent estimators. Section 56 2.2 gives a description of the measures of market disorder and the data. Section 2.3 briefly mentions the probit model and gives the estimation output with respect to probit model. Then Section 2.4 gives a description of the tobit model and the censored least absolute deviation method in the context of intervention . The empirical results with respect to these models, are also given in section 2.4. Finally, section 2.5 gives a brief conclusion. 2.2. Modeling Intervention Behaviour We propose that a central bank intervenes with the objective of minimizing disorderliness over time in the foreign exchange market for its currency, depending on its perception of the effectiveness of intervention. First, they might wish to reduce disorderliness by returning the exchange rate to what they perceive to be the appropriate trend to be. With a very long horizon, purchasing power parity considerations might drive intervention behaviour. See Dominquez and Frankel (1993) and Frenkel and Stadtrnann (2001). Secondly a central bank may be concerned about disorderly conditions in foreign exchange markets that might show up as excessive fluctuations in exchange rates through higher volatility, due to higher levels of uncertainty and trading. They may intervene to cahn the market by trying to reduce uncertainty. This uncertainty may be measured by the conditional volatility of the daily change in the exchange rate. Most empirical studies include the deviation of exchange rate flom some targets levels and a measure of volatility of the exchange rates. There is no clear answer to the 57 appropriate measures of the disorderly market conditions and it is rather difficult to reach this information. The target level for the exchange rate is thought to present past levels of the exchange rate. This is not to say that the exchange is considered to be at a desirable level in previous days. It merely allows one to test whether the central bank systematically ‘leaned against the wind’ and tried to smooth deviations flom the m-days moving average of the exchange rate. Central banks appear to intervene whenever current exchange rate movements deviate significantly flom a trend. The deviation measure (devt) is modeled in (2.1) as the deviation of the current exchange rate flom a moving average exchange rate. m 1 m devt =10q1n(St)—-In(— 2 St —i)] (2.1) m i=1 Different studies include different length of a representative moving average. Almekinders and Eij ffinger (1994,1996) include the deviation of DM/USD rate flom the seven-day moving average . Humpage (1999) uses ten-day moving average. Frenkel and Stadtrnann (2001) and Frenkel, Pierdzioch and Stadtrnann (2003) use a 25- day moving average as a short run target level of exchange rate, and purchasing power parity as a long run target. Kim and Sheen (2002), Neely (1998) and Le Baron (1999) use a ISO—day moving average rate and claim it is the common choice among market traders. 58 As for the volatility measure, the dominant choice seems to be the conditional variance of the log return of the exchange rate estimated with a GARCH(1,1) model. The conditional variance is estimated using the following model: 100[In(St) — In(St_1)] = ,u + at (2.2a) 0,2 = a) + 016,42 + 60,42 (2.20) where z, is i.i.d (0,1). There is considerable evidence that shows central banks respond to deviations of the spot rate flom some target level by leaning against the wind, and to exchange rate volatility, by market calming down. Ahnekinders and Eijffinger (1994,1996), Frenkel and Stadtmann (2001), and Kim and Sheen (2002) find evidence of leaning against the wind and of market calming. They show that both target deviations and volatility matter. Baillie and Osterberg (1997), find that while a GARCH measure of the deviations of conditional volatility flom unconditional volatility has no effect on intervention, (1 eviations o f the spot rates from the targets d o m atter. A s in B aillie and Osterberg (1997), Ito and Yabu (2004) show that deviations flom the target motivates intervention. Dominquez (1998) and McKenzie (2004) find no significant intervention response to volatility of exchange rate movements. It is difficult to reach the appropriate measures for disorderly market conditions. According to the standby agreement signed by the IMF in early 1995, the exchange rate policy was based on the idea of utilizing exchange rates as a nominal anchor in curbing 59 inflation. The increase in the foreign exchange basket, defined as 1.5 German marks and 1 US dollar, was targeted to increase by as much as the targeted monthly inflation rates. The basket was revised as 1 US dollar and 0.77 Euro by the introduction of the Euro in 1999. Deviations flom the targeted inflation rate were seen in certain periods and the targets for the basket were adjusted accordingly. Target values of the data for this period are unavailable. The FX interventions of the CBRT, after the switch to the floating exchange rate regime, were directed towards damping the excessive volatility in the FX level without affecting its long-run value. In this analysis, we use several lengths of a representative moving average values such as 5, 25, 50, 125 days for both the managed and flee float periods. This enables us to see the response of central bank to short and long-term deviations. 2.3.1. Probit Model Econometric modeling of the daily intervention series has some practical challenges. The dependent variable, e. g. the intervention series, is discontinous and so modeling it using standard regression techniques is inappropriate. The intervention variable takes zero values for the majority of the observations in a sample while the explanatory variables are not zero. This implies a non-linear relationship because the observed quantities do not increase or decrease approximately in proportion to the levels of the explanatory variables. We generate a binary choice dependent variable corresponding to intervention/no intervention outcomes for each of the two types of interventions and model the probability of each type of intervention. As an initial approach, we follow 60 Baillie and Osterberg (1997), Dominquez (1998), and Kim and Sheen (2002) and adopt a probit model and estimate the probability of positive and negative interventions of the CBRT‘s foreign exchange market interventions. In a binary response model, the aim is to find the response probability P(y=1|x)=P(y=l|x,,x2,....x,) (2.3) where x denotes the full set of explanatory variables. Wooldridge (2000) mentions that the linear probability model is simple to estimate but has some important disadvantages- the fitted probabilities can be less than zero or greater than one and the partial effect of any explanatory variable is constant. To avoid these limitations, a class of binary response models is proposed and, among the nonlinear functions suggested, probit is the most commonly used model. Because of the nonlinear nature of E ( y | x) , a maximum likelihood estimation is used (MLE). The MLE is consistent , asymptotically normal and efficient. Likelihood ratio statistics (LR) commonly are used to test multiple restrictions in probit models. We define US,bas the amount of dollar purchases vis-a-vis TL by the CBRT in time periodt. Similarlywe define US,’ asthe amountofdollar sales visa visTLintime period t. Itb =1, (18,150 and Itb = 0, otherwise (2.4a) 1,5 =1, US,S)O and 1,3 = 0, otherwise (2.4b) 61 Then the following two equations are estimated separately by using a Maximum Likelihood Estimation Itb = 71b + yzbdevt_1(m) + 73b0't_12 + gtb (2.5a) and s _ s s (m) s 2 s It —y1 + 72 devt_1 + 73 0',_1 + at (2.5b) It is important to mention that we also include the lagged value of the dependent variable among the regressors. A 2004 study by De Jong and Woutersen considers dynamic time series binary choice model in detail. In this study, the data is provided by the Central Bank of Turkey. The data sample consists of both daily spot bid rates, and daily intervention variables flom November 1, 1993 through December 31, 2003. Intervention values are in millions of US dollars. Exchange rate policies are different through out the period. The analysis has been done separately for managed float and flee float regimes excluding the crisis periods. So two subsamples of the data are taken and the first has the daily amount of net dollar purchases (sales) and daily spot bid rates date flom January 2, 1995 through December 31, 1999 when the exchange rate policy was managed float. We have the estimations for only the flee float regime which dates flom February 27, 2001 through December 31, 2003. The data used in the estimations will have different starting values because the devH'" are calculated starting flom January 2, 1995 (for managed float) and flom February 27, 2001 62 25 (for flee float). For example, when we estimate the reaction firnction using devH and volatility, the estimation sample dates flom February, 7 1995 to December 31, 1999 for the managed float period and dates flom April, 10 2001 to December 31, 2003 for the 5 flee float period. When we use devH 0 and volatility, the estimation sample dates flom March 15, 1995 to December 31, 1999 for the managed float, and May, 16 2001 to December 31, 2003 for the flee float period. 2.3.2 Estimation Results The estimation output for the managed float regime is shown in table 2.1. We take all the representative values of deviation flom the m-day moving average and estimate the reaction function and include only the significant ones. For the managed float period, we find that deviation flom both five and 25 day moving average increases the probability of sale while deviation flom the 50 day moving average and volatility decreases the probability of sale. The probability of purchase of US dollars is increased by the deviation flom a 50 day moving average and is decreased by the deviation flom a 25 day moving average. The probability of purchase is not determined by the conditional volatility. Lagged values of intervention increase the probability of intervention next day. The empirical finding is consistent with the monetary policy of the central bank during this period. The bank aims to achieve stability in real exchange rates. 63 Table 2.1: Estimation of Probit Intervention Model (‘0 Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard En'or Coefficient Standard Error C 0.75 0.120 0.90 0.12 DEV...’ -011 0.09 0.19 ' 0.11 om,” -0.28 0.100 0.28 0.11 DEVHS" 0.16 0.060 0.13 " 0.06 o,,’ 0.27 0.26 -0.56 ‘ 0.32 1,,” 0.980 0.080 14’ 0.94 0.08 McFadden 112 0,12 0.13 LRstatistic(5 01) 199 203 1"” 1209 1209 ('0 Full period of 15 March, 1995 through 31 December, 1999. (b) T denotes sample size 0') denotes 10% significance level (fl) denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level b b 2 1t =71 +72bdth—1(m)+73b0't—1 +€tb where 1,” = 1, US,”>0 with 1,” = 0,0therwise and 2 Its = 713 + yzsdevt_1(m) + 935034 + as where 1,3 =1, UStS )0 and Its = 0,0therwise 64 The estimation output for the free float regime has differences from the managed float. During the flee float regime, the CBRT announced that the aim is not to affect the level of the exchange rate. The aim is to smooth the excess volatility. Interventions do not affect the long-run equilibrium of the exchange rate. Tables 2.2 gives the estimation output for the probit analysis during the flee float regime. We find that the probability of sale of US dollars is increased by the current volatility of the exchange rate and the deviation flom both the five and 125-day moving average. Deviations flom the five-day and 50-day moving average increase the probability of purchase while deviations flom 125 day moving average decrease the probability of purchases. A lagged value of intervention increases the probability of intervention next day. These results indicate that the central bank is more responsive to longer term deviations and volatility during the flee float regime. 65 — Table 2.2: Estimation of Probit Intervention Model 0') Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error C -111 0.13 4.15 1.04 DEVHS 0.13 ” 0.06 0.22 ” 0.10 111sz50 0.05 ‘ 0.02 -024 ” 0.11 Driv,,,'25 -011 0.01 0.23 ” 0.10 of 0.02 0.11 0.44 ” 0.20 1,," 1.45 0.15 1.: 2.58 0.35 McFadden R2 0.45 0.820 LR statistic(5 d1) 339 335 1“” 587 587 m Full period of 29 August, 2001 through 31 December, 2003. (b) T denotes sample size 0*) denotes 10% significance level 0") denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level Itb =71b + 72bdth—1(m)+ 73bat—12 + 31b where 1,1’ = 1, US,”)0 with 1,” = 0,0therwise and 2 Its =71“? +yzsdevt_1(m) +73SO't_1 +£ts where 1,5 =1, UStS)0 and ItS = 0,0therwise 66 2.4.1. Tobit and Censored Least Absolute Deviation Model Another important kind of limited dependent variable model is one that is continuous over strictly positive values but is zero for a flaction of the population. Let y be a variable continuous over strictly positive values but that takes on zero with positive probability. The Tobit model is most easily defined as a latent variable model where y. = :30 + xfl + u,u Ix ~ Normal(0,0'2) (2.6) y = maX(0,y') (2.7) The latent variable y' satisfies the classical linear model assumptions where it has a normal, homoscedastic distribution with a linear conditional mean. Equation (2.7) implies that the observed variable,y, equals y'when y‘ >0 and 0, otherwise. Maximum likelihood estimation is used. Both heteroscedasticity and nonnormality result in the Tobit estimator ,6 being inconsistent for ,6. This inconsistency occurs because the derived density of y given x hinges crucially on y' | x ~ Normal(xfl,0'2). Tests for heteroscedasticity and non-normality in the latent variable equation are easily constructed. A useful test for heteroscedasticity is suggested by Wooldridge (2002) and obtained by assuming Var(u |x)=0'2 exp(26), where z is a lxq subvector of x (2 does not include a constant). The q restrictions H0 :6 = 0, can be tested using the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) statistic. We can also construct tests of non-normality that only require a standard Tobit estimation. The most convenient of these are derived as the conditional 67 moment tests. See Pagan and Vella (1989). Powell (1984) suggests that a least absolute deviation estimation is a natural approach for censored data when the assumption of normality of the errors is suspect. It is possible to estimate ,6 consistently without assuming a particular distribution for uand without even assuming that uand x are independent. Consider again the latent variable model , but where the median of u ,given x, is zero and y° = xfl + u, Med(u | x) = 0 (2.8) Med( y Ix) = max[0,Med(y‘ lx)] = max(0,xfl) (2.9) The equation (2.8) implies that Med ( y' Ix) = xfl , so that the median of y' is linear in x. Importantly, equation (2.8) holds up under assumption (2.9) and no further distributional assumptions are needed. Assumption (2.9) suggests estimating ,3 by solving mflin(1/N)Z| y, — max(0, xifl) | (2.10) i=1 The 1 cast a bsolute d eviations e stimator for the c ensored r egression m odel (CLAD) minimizes the sum of absolute deviations of y, flom max(0, x,,B) over all ,6. To obtain the CLAD estimates we use the methodology described in De Jong and Herrera (2004). Thus, we use an iterative linear programming algorithm, which was 68 proposed by Buchinsky (1994). This procedure amounts to first solving the linear programming (LP) representation of the optimization problem ngin{T1_1;[%sgn(y, -/3'x.)(y. mm} (2.11) to obtain the 5(1) estimates. Then solve the LP problem for 5(2) using the observations for which I: (wx, > 0. This procedure is repeated until the set of observation used in two consecutive iterations is the s arne. Standard e rrors for 3 are 0 btained according to the method employed by De Jong and Herrera (2004 ). The reported standard errors for the Tobit estimates are the quasi-maximum likelihood standard errors. 2.4.2Estimation Output In this section, we first estimate the reaction function using a Tobit model and check for homoscedasticity and normality. The empirical evidence shows that we have a heteroscedasticity and non-normality problem. Then we estimate the reaction function using a C LAD m ethod where the n ew e stimator is b oth c onsistent and a syrnptotically normal. F irst, w e e stimate the T obit m odel for a m anaged float p eriod. T he empirical evidence is in Tables 2.3 and 2.4. We take the same deviation flom the moving average values as we use in probit model. Deviation flom both the short- and medium-term appears to have a significant effect Granger causing the sale of US dollars. The sale of US dollars is decreased by a deviation flom the long-term and conditional volatility . 69 While the purchase of US dollar is increased by the deviation flom long term, both the deviation from short-term and volatility has no effect on the p urchases of U S dollars. When we find that Jarque-Bera and LM tests indicate both non-normality and heteroscedasticity, we used CLAD method. With respect to the purchase of US dollars, CLAD results are the same as Tobit results except the volatility appears to have a significant effect Granger causing the purchase of US dollar. With respect to the sale of US dollars, contrary to Tobit results, deviation flom the short- and long-term appear to have no significant effect. In all these estimations we find that a lagged value of intervention increases intervention next day. 70 fl Table 2.3: Estimation of Tobit Intervention Model Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error c -61.95 13.65 -1 13.56 18.93 DEVMs -8.56 9.55 26.35 ‘ 15.16 DEV,_,25 -35.31 10.91 49.75 15.52 DEV,_,5° 18.74 5.97 -24.59 6.39 6,,2 14.11 24.60 -90.46 " 44.75 1,," 0.66 0.07 It-1' 0.77 0.07 ‘ LM-Test‘b’ 823 926 skewness 4.10 5.03 kurtosis 27.54 48.38 Jarque-Bera 33755 108877 T“) 1209 1209 0" Full period of 15 March, 1995 through 31 December, 1999. (b) Lagrange Multiplier statistic to test for heteroscedasticity. (f) T denotes sample size ( )denotes 10% significance level (:2 denotes 5% significance level ( )denotes 1% significance level y. = A, +xfl+u,u Ix ~ Norma1(0,0'2) y = maX(0,y') where yequals y. when y*>0 and 0, otherwise. 71 —a Table 2.4: Estimation of Powell Censored Least Absolute Devration ) Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error 0 -13.07 1.61 -102.85 25.86 DEVM‘ 1.13 1.01 -4.87 13.55 015v...25 -7.22 1.21 30.24 " 15.42 new,“ 4.83 0.66 -O.88 8.40 o,,,’ 30.31 2.57 90.22 " 44.22 1,," 0.37 0.01 lot“ 0.51 0.04 M kurtosis 24.36 16.37 Jarque-Bera 25521 10266 7"” 412 249 (a) Full period of 15 March, 1995 through 31 December, 1999 (b) T denotes sample size (*) denotes 10% significance level ('7 denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level y'=x,B+u, Med(u|x)=0 Med (y I x) = max[0, Med ( y. |x)] = max(0,x,6) mflin(1/N)Zl y, — max(0,x.-fl)l 72 Tables 2.5 and 2.6 gives the empirical evidence for both Tobit and CLAD estimations during the flee float regime. First we estimate a Tobit model and find that sale of US dollars is determined by the current volatility of the exchange rate and deviation flom long-term. With respect to the purchase of US dollar while deviation flom long-tenn decreases the purchase of US dollar, deviation flom both short- and the medium term increases. Lagged values of intervention increase the probability of intervention next day. When we find evidence for heteroscedasticity and non-normality, we estimate CLAD and contrary to Tobit results, we find that neither the representative deviations nor volatility has an effect on the sale the US dollars. The other interesting difference between the Tobit results is with respect to the purchases of US dollars. Deviation flom the short-term has no effect on the purchase of US dollar. The sample size in flee float regime is smaller than the one in managed float. So we suspect small sample size bias for CLAD estimatons. Khan and Powell (2001) suggests two-step estimators for these models to overcome the finite sample bias. In this respect an interesting extension of this research would be to use the two-step estimators method suggested by Khan and Powell (2001) in further research. 73 Table 2.5: Estimation of Tobit Intervention Modelm- Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error C -136.79 40.56 -58.58 17.44 DEVH5 12.20 ' 7.04 1.63 1.26 DEV,_,5° 12.39 4.54 -4.87 1.79 DEVHm -20.68 5.58 4.82 1.82 6,,2 4.49 13.91 5.32 1.69 1,,b 0.16 " 0.07 Itt' 0.69 0.24 LM-Test‘b’ 341 121 skewness 11.98 23.81 kurtosis 181.48 573.53 Jarque-Bera 793204 8017040 T“) 587 587 1" Full period of 29 August, 2001 through 31 December, 2003. (b) Lagrange Multiplier statistic to test for heteroscedasticity. “’ T denotes sample size (') denotes 10% significance level 0') denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level y. = flo + xfl + u,u | x ~ Normal(0,0'2) y = maX(0.y') where yequals y‘ when y*>0 and 0, otherwise. 74 Table 2.6: Estimation of Powell Censored Least Absolute Deviation“) — Purchases of US Dollars Sales of US Dollars Coefficient Standard En'or Coefficient Standard Error 0 -6.86 13.19 -1044 15.92 01va5 1.18 3.62 0.04 0.69 015v...so 6.92 2.29 -1.08 1.66 new” 6.92 1.91 1.04 1.55 of -1054 3.91 0.68 1.44 1,," 0.06 " 0.02 Iii' 0.90 0.11 kurtosis 139.18 18.25 Jarque-Bera 458938 5946 7"” 186 77 “0 Full period of 29 August, 2001 through 31 December, 2003. (b) T denotes sample size 1') denotes 10% significance level ('1') denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level y'=x,B+u, Med(u|x)=0 Med (y Ix) = max[0, Med ( y. I x)] = max(0,x,6) mpin(l / 07);] y,- — max(0, x716) I 75 2.5 Conclusion This chapter investigates the motivations for central bank intervention. We estimate the reaction function for b oth the m anaged float and free float regime separately. The empirical evidence gives different result for different regimes. First the probit model for managed float was estimated and it was found that the probability of sales of US dollars is increased by a deviation flom both the short- and medium-term and the probability of purchases is increased by the deviation flom the long-term. The probability of intervention is not determined by the conditional volatility for managed float and Tobit estimates give similar results. Contrary to managed float period, both tobit and probit estimations indicate that the central bank is more responsive to volatility during a flee float regime. While the sales of US dollars is determined by volatility and the deviation flom long-term, purchase is determined by deviation flom short— and medium term. When we find non-normality and heteroscedasticity in Tobit results, we estimate all the reaction functions using a CLAD method so that we have consistent and asymptotically normal estimators. For managed float, different flom the Tobit results, we find evidence that purchases of US dollar is increased by volatility and sales are only determined by deviation flom medium term. For flee-float regime, we find that neither the deviation flom the 5,50 and 125 days moving average values nor volatility have an effect on the sales of the US dollars. In all the estimations, the common finding is that 76 lagged value of intervention increases the intervention next day for both the managed and flee float regime. The sample size in flee float regime is smaller than the one in managed float. So we suspect small sample size bias for CLAD estimatons. Khan and Powell (2001) suggest two-step estimators for these models to overcome the finite sample bias. In this respect an interesting extension of this research would be to use the two-step estimators method suggested by Khan and Powell (2001) in further research. 77 CHAPTER 3 Threshold Non-linear Estimation of the Central Bank Intervention Reaction Function 3.1 Introduction In chapter two, the intervention reaction function is estimated using probit, tobit and censored least absolute deviation methods . In this chapter, we adopt a different approach and use a threshold model, with a view to extending our empirical understanding of the detenninants of the Central Bank of Turkey‘s intervention. This method is first used by Jun (2004). Jun(2004) mentions that the fliction method adopted by Ahnekinders and Eij ffinger (1996) and Kim and Sheen (2002) is not better than a simple linear model. A friction model involves specifying three separate distributional assumptions for the intervention series, and corresponds to the three different states of the intervention outcome. This approach allows a direct modeling of the relationship between the interventions and their determinants . The central bank is assumed to react to market conditions and constraints, but only after an intervention threshold is reached. The threSholds may differ for positive and negative interventions (purchase/sale of the foreign 78 currency) and these may be estimated. Jun (2004) tests the fliction hypothesis with a more flexible model using a threshold model that does not restrict the dependent variable to zero in the middle regime. In contrast to the friction model, the threshold variable that determines the regimes is one of the measures of the disorderly market conditions and it can be estimated by the method of least squares without assumptions regarding error distribution. Residual based test for misspecification are also applicable using this modeling approach. Section 3.2 gives a detailed description of the specification, ' estimation and test strategies of a threshold model in the context of intervention (Hansen, 1999, 2000). The empirical results with respect to the threshold model are given in section 3.3 and section 3.4 gives a brief conclusion. 3. 2 Estimation Of Threshold Models The linear model of central bank reaction function is y: =Xtfl+£t (3.1) where y, d enotes the actual p urchases (sales) 0 f U S dollar and an m -regime threshold model allows the parameter vector ,8 in the linear model (3.1) to change m times based on the values of the threshold variable 77,. A three regime threshold model can be written as yt = xtfll-K’k 5 7t) + xtflz-IU’I S 771 S 72) + xtfl3-“flt Z 72) + 81 (32) where I (.) is the indicator function, and ,6,- = (fit-0,6,1 ...... ,Bl-k) , i = 1,2,3. 79 If x, consists of lags of y, only, it is called a threshold autoregressive (TAR) model. In addition, if 77, is one of the lagged y,, the model becomes a self- exciting threshold autoregressive (SETAR) mode]. Some exogenous variables are used, such as deviation and volatility measures as explanatory variables, in addition to the autoregressive terms of y,. The model is called a threshold model (Hansen, 2000). In our analysis, the threshold variable 77, is one of the exogenous variables. Specifically, we compare the dev(,_,) and 004,2 , and choose the one that minimizes the sum of squared residuals as the threshold variable. The parameters (81,82,63,7,,72) can be estimated using conditional least squares. If the thresholds are given, the model becomes linear in the rest of the parameters and can be written as y, = 3,6 + 8', (3.3) where (9 = (,61, ,62, ,63) and the 3(k+1) row vector .9, is 37 =(x713-1(777 S7’1) 1115 1(71 5 '77 S7’2) xtfl-“Ut 2 72)) (3-4) The 6 in (3.3) can then be estimated by OLS. In defining the set of threshold observations Q = {77, It =1,....T} (3.5) For each pair of (77,.,77j)e(22 where i,j=1 ...... T and 77,071., substitute (77,,77j) for (71 , 72) in (3.4). Estimating (3.3) by using OLS, the sum of squared residuals S(77,., 77 j) is obtained and is defined as T 2 8071.77,) = t21(yt - 3149) (3.6) 80 Then the pair of (77,, 77 ,) that minimizes the sum of squared residuals will be the threshold A A A A A estimates (7,, 7,). The estimates of the other parameters (,6, , ,6, , ,6 3) , are obtained as the OLS estimates of equation (3.2) with 7, = 7, and 7, = 7,. This procedure requires T (T — l)/ 2 OLS regressions. Since we have two candidates for the threshold variable, the whole estimation process requires T (T — l) OLS regressions. Although this is not a problem in the estimation stage, it becomes a critical problem in the hypothesis testing where the computation o f b ootstrap p -values requires thousands o f replications o f this procedure. In order to reduce this computational burden, Hansen (1999) proposes a two- step estimation procedure where the thresholds are estimated sequentially, one by one. First we estimate a two-regime model as yt = Mal-[(777 5 7) + 35702-1077 2 7’) + 9': (3-7) A A A The threshold estimate 7 for the two regime models is the same as either 71 or 7, and useful in reducing the running time for the estimation of the three regime model of (3.2). A ' It is also true that a, = ,6, if 7 = 7,,or a, = ,63 if 7 = 7,. The two step approach proposed by Hansen (1999) consists of the following steps : A 1) Estimate the two regime model and obtain 7 which is the element of Q = {77, It = 1,....T} that minimizes the sum of squared residuals. 2) Estimate the three regime model (3.3) after setting the 7,and7, in (3.4) as either (7. 77.) or (2.7) for each 77. 6 0. By assumvtion. 7. (72. 81 Hansen (1999) mentions that if the true model is a three-regime model but a two- A regime m odel is e stimated, 7, will b e c onsistent for o ne p air 0 f the (7, , 7,). Then if (7, , 7,) is estimated by least-squares enforcing that one element of 7 equals 7, , then the A second stage estimate 7, will be consistent for the remaining element of the pair (7, , 7,). Furthermore, this method is iterated at least once; that is, (7,, 7,) is estimated by least A squares enforcing the constraint that one element of 7equals 7, , yielding a refined A estimate 7, . This iteration makes the estimates of (7,, 7,) obtained by the two-step method asymptotically efficient. If there are T elements in Q for each of the N candidates of the threshold variable, then the two-step approach requires (2T-1) N regressions. In order to estimate the multi- regime model of (3.2), some restrictions must be imposed on the range of 7,and7, so that each regime has at least the minimum required number of observations . One obvious requirement is that the number of observation of each regime, 7:. for i = 1,2,3 must be greater or equal to the number of explanatory variables, k+1. Another more important requirement is concerned with the asymptotic properties of the estimators and test statistics. For a linear model, we can rely on consistency of the OLS estimator if T is large. Similarly, with three regime m odel o f (3.2), w e n eed to h ave large I, for each regime because the conditional least squares procedure is equivalent to splitting the sample into three sub-samples and then estimating ,6, using only T, observations. This 82 involves three smaller regressions and is faster than running one large regression with equation (3.3). Hansen (1999) explains that it is necessary to have T, / T 2 r for some r)0 as T —> 00. In practice, however, it is inevitable to choose 2' somewhat arbitrarily. Hansen (1999) suggests r = 0.10. The next step is to test if the nonlinear model in (3.2) is a better specification than the linear model in equation (3.1). This is equivalent to testing the null hypothesis of H01=fl1=flz =fl3=fl (3-8) Hansen(l999) suggests a test statistics of S _ F = T(—LT:—T—) (3.9) where S , is the sum of squared residuals flom LS estimation of the linear model (3.1) and S, is the sum of squared residuals flom the three-regime model (3.2). When the thresholds are known, F is asymptotically equivalent to the usual F statistic. Since the thresholds are unknown and not identified under (3.8), however, F follows an unknown asymptotic distribution. Bootstrapping methods are relied on to compute the p-values with and without the conditional heteroscedasticity assumption. Under the h omoscedastic e rror a ssumption, a s et 0 f b ootstrap e rrors a re 0 btained, with E = {5, It: 1, ..... T} by randomly drawing T times with the replacement flom the OLS residuals é={é, |t=1, ..... T} of the linear model (3.1). A set of data on the dependent variable is generated then by 83 A ~ ~ ~ yr = X: 6+ 3t (3.10) ~ ~ ~ ~ where x, = (1,dev(,_1)m,0(,_1)2,y,_1,y,_2,....,y,_p )' and 6 is the OLS estimate of equation (3.1). Substituting )7, for y, in the linear model and the threshold models, the models are re-estimated to get one value of E which is f =T(§°—§—§‘—) (3.11) where S, and S, are the sum of squared residuals flom the linear model and the threshold model, respectively, with bootstrap data. Out of 1000 replications, the proportion of F‘ greater than F is the approximate p-value. Under heteroscedastic error assumption, the procedure is a bit more complicated because we have to impose heteroscedasticity on the bootstrap errors a. First each A element of the OLS residual vector 5 is divided by an estimate of the conditional standard deviation (Jiz) to obtain a set of homoscedastic errors of ~ ~ ~ 8={£t |8,=s,/ h,,t=l, ....... T} (3.12) The conditional variance estimate, hr , is obtained as the fitted value flom an auxiliary A regression of 8,2 on x,2 = (l,[deV(,_1)(m)]2,[a(,_1)2]2,y(,_1)2,y(,_2)2, ...... ,y(,_p)2)' 84 A ef=x35+m (3B) A A h=x35 0J0 A where U, is an error term and 6 is the vector of OLS estimates in that auxiliary regression. Now the random draws are flom these standardized errors of 8 and the t-th bootstrap error 6‘: is ~ z ~ 8t =8! ht (3.15) ~A ~ WhCI‘C ht =Xt26 and xt =(l,deV(,_1)2,0’(,_1)2,y,_1,y,_2, ...... ’yt—p). once the value of 6, is given, the value of the dependent variable y, is computed by (3.10). It is A important to note that h, :1: h, and x. at x,. x, contains lags of y, , h, , a, as well as y, , and must be computed recursively. The rest of the bootstrap procedure is the same as the homoscedastic case. If the linearity hypothesis is rejected in favor of the threshold model, Hansen (1997, 2000), in turn, provides a method to construct an asymptotically valid confidence interval for the threshold of the two regime model. Unfortunately, to date the asymptotic distributions of the threshold estimators ('71, 72) are not developed for three or higher order models. 85 3.3 Tests for Nonlinearity and Estimation Output of Reaction Function We estimate the reaction functions for the Central Bank of Turkey for both managed float and flee float regime. For each of the subsamples, the two regime and three-regime threshold reaction functions are estimated using GAUSS programs. This estimation precedes hypothesis tests, but begins with the results of the tests whether two-regime or three regime threshold nonlinearity exists in the reaction function. The tests of nonlinearity for a managed float regime are presented in Table 3.1. The test statistics F 12 for a o ne-regime, v ersus a two-regime linear model is 2 7.35. The p - values are computed as the proportion of those bootstrap simulations out of 1000 replications that have the F -statistic larger than 27.35. When the errors in the linear model are assumed to be homoscedastic, the p-value is 0.01. Therefore,we reject (fail to accept ) the null hypothesis of linearity against a two-regime threshold-nonlinearity at 5% level. Correcting for heteroscedasticity, the p-value is about 0.37 and we do not reject the null of linear reaction function. Against the three-regime alternative, the F13 statistic flom the estimation is 50.09. The bootstrap p-value is 0.02 with homoscedasticity. Therefore we reject the null of the linear reaction function at 5 %. With heteroscedasticity, the p-value is 0.27 and fail to reject the linearity. Since we cannot reject linearity against three- regime nonlinearity, it is not suprising to find that the three-regime model is no better than a two-regime model. The F23 statistic is clearly significant with homoscedasticity assumption but not with the heteroscedasticity assumption for the regression errors. 86 Table:3.1 Test for Non-linearity Managed Float Period (February 7, 1995- December,31 1999) F-statistlcs p-values Homoscedastic Heteroscedastic 27.35 0.01 0.37 50.09 0.02 0.27 22.24 0.06 0.2 87 The estimation results can be found in Table 3.2. The second column is for the linear model, the next two columns are for the two-regime threshold model, and the last three columns contain the estimation results with the three-regime model. As for the linear model, among the three measures of the disorderly market conditions (devHS, devH25 , 0',_,2 ), the estimate of devH5 is significant at 5 % and the estimate of 0',_,2 is significant at 10%. The coefficients of devH5 and devH25 have an expected negative signs implying that the central bank‘s intervention tends to be against the wind. On the contrary, the coefficient of 0',_,2 is positive. Out of the two lags of the dependent variable, both of them are significant at 1% level. Overall, the implication is that recent interventions increase the expected amount of intervention in the near future. These two lags are enough to eliminate the serial correlation in the residuals. Ljung-Box test statistics indicate that there are no serial correlations in the residuals up to order of 10 (Q00) = 13.2, with a 5% critical value of 18.31). However, there is strong evidence for heteroscedasticity (Q2(10)=107.48). A separate regression of the squared residuals on squared regressors (as reported in table 3.3), indicates that the errors are heteroscedastic and, therefore, White‘s heteroscedasticity consistent standard errors are reported in table 3.2. 88 Table 3.2: Estimation of Threshold Intervention Reaction Function'I (n,=dev,,,s) Variable Constant Dev,_,(5) 2 91-1 Yi-l yt-Z T R2 F,.=0 71 72 2 R (.11) Skewness Kurtosis 010 0’... Linear Two-regime - Three-regime Regime I Regimejz Regime I Regime 2 lRegime 3 0.04 0.03 -0.05 -0.01 0.72 ' -0.05 (0.07) (0.09) (0.25) (0.10) (0.43) (0.25) -0.13 ” -0.07 -0.12 -0.104 -0.83 ' -0.12 (0.06) (0.09) (0.15) (0.13) (0.43) (0.15) -0.01 -0.002 0.002 0.015 -0.04 0.002 (0.02) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.07) (0.05) 0.26 ' 0.19 0.57 " 0.192 0.34 0.57 " (0.15) (0.27) (0.27) (0.31) (0.91) (0.27) 0.37 0.29 0.59 0.344 0.26 0.59 (0.04) (0.04) (0.10) (0.05) (0.06) (0.10) 0.18 0.18 0.13 0.291 0.09 ' 0.13 (0.04) (0.04) (0.08) (0.06) (0.05) (0.08) 1234 939 295 545 394 295 I 0.25 0.19 0.37 0.26 0.14 0.37 84.94 0.94 0.57 0.94 0.25 0.27 0.28 -0.58 -0.57 -0.62 13.31 12.6 12.34 13.2 11.89 13.63 107.48 122.19 114.88 (a) Full period of 7 February, 1995 through 31 December, 1999. a” Numbers in parathesis are heteroscedasticity adjusted standard errors. “’ F...=0 tests overall significance except the constant. (:1 denotes 10% significance level (“i denotes 5% significance level ( ’ denotes 1% significance level yt = 101511077 5 71) + xtflz-IO’I S 777 S 72) + 367163-1077 ->- 72) + 81 where I (.) is the indicator function, and ,6,- = (6,0,6,1 ...... 6,7,) , i =1,2,3. 89 Table 3.3. Least Square Estimation of Conditional Variance Managed Float Period (Februag 7, 1995- December,3l 1999) Variable Estimate Standard Error Constant 0.87 0.15 Dev(5),.,2 0.08 0.05 Dev(25),_,z -0.012 0.01 Vol...2 .052 0.22 y..,2 0.11 0.06 yez’ 0.04 0.03 F-Test 40.19 (p-value) 0.00 90 Tests for nonlinearity (Table 3.1) show that a rejection of both two-regime and three- regime models versus the linear model. Despite this result, it is worth mentioning that with two regime model, the optimal threshold variable is estimated to be dev,.15 and the point estimate of the threshold 77, is 0.94. This positive threshold indicates that the strongest non-linearity in the central bank‘s reaction function exists when the dollar appreciates rapidly. This indicates that, in light of the history of the exchange rate policy under managed float, the central bank is more sensitive to appreciation of the dollar. In the case of the three-regime model, the estimate of the second threshold is also positive. The test results for both the non-linearity and the estimation output of the reaction firnction for the flee float regime are given in tables 3.4 and 3.5. 91 Table:3.4 Test for Non-linearity Free Float Period (April, 10 2001- December,3l 2003) F-statistics p—values Homoscedastic Heteroscedastic F12 25.64 0.05 0.37 F” 48.29 0.39 0.41 F23 21.83 0.33 0.25 92 The test s tatistics F 12 for a o ne-regime linear m odel v ersus a two-regime model is 25.64. The p-values are computed as the proportion of those bootstrap simulations out of 1000 replications that have the F-statistic > 25.64. When the errors in the linear model are assumed to be homoscedastic, the p-value is 0.05. Therefore, we reject (fail to accept ) the null hypothesis of linearity against a two-regime threshold-nonlinearity at 5% level. With correction for heteroscedasticity, the p-value is about 0.37 and we do not reject the null of linear reaction function. Against a three-regime alternative, the F13 statistic from the e stimation is 4 8.29. The b ootstrap p -value is 0 .39 w ith h omoscedasticity and 0 .41 with heteroscedasticity. and we fail to reject the linearity. Since we cannot reject linearity against three-regime nonlinearity , it is not suprising to see that the three-regime model is no better than a two-regime model. The F23 statistic is clearly insignificant with or without the heteroscedasticity assumption for the regression errors. The estimation results are given in table 3.5. As for the linear model, among the three 5 measures of disordely market conditions (dev,.15 , devH2 , 0’,_,2) , only the estimate of 0',_,2 is significant (1 % level) and has an expected negative sign implying that the central bank‘s intervention tends to be against the volatility, but not the deviation flom the trend. Out of the three lags of the dependent variables, all of them are significant at 1% and 5%. Overall, the implication is that recent interventions increase the expected amount of intervention in the near future. These three lags are enough to eliminate serial correlation in the residuals. Ljung-Box test statistics indicate that there are no serial correlations in the residuals up to order of 10 (Q(10) = 13.35, 5% critical value 18.31). Also, there is no evidence for heteroscedasticity (Q2(10)=0.12). A separate regression of 93 the squared residuals on squared regressors, as reported in table 3.6 also indicates that the errors are not heteroscedastic. As a result, a two-regime threshold is preferred to linearity and three regimes. 94 Table 3.5: Estimation of Threshold Intervention Reaction Function' (1156,42) Variable Linear Two-regime Three-regime I Regime I Regime T Regime 1 Regime 2 Regime 3 Constant 0.13 0.29 0.08 0.31 -0.002 0.015 (0.03) (0.40) (0.03) (0.40) (0.36) (0.03) Devm‘” -0.03 -004 -002 -004 0.08 “ 003 ° (0.02) (0.09) (0.02) (0.09) (0.04) (0.02) Dev...” -0002 -0.1 ' 0.002 -010 ‘ -002 0.011 (0.01) (0.06) (0.01) (0.06) (0.01) (0.01) 6.12 -0.05 ‘” -O.6 -004 -0.65 0.14 -003 (0.01) (1.05) (0.01) (1.04) (0.53) (0.01) y... 0.13 0.04 " 0.32 0.04 “ 1.02 0.21 " (0.05) (0.02) (0.12) (0.02) (0.34) (0.09) y.2 0.08 0.24 0.04' 0.24 -0012 0.03 (0.03) (0.20) (0.02) (0.20) (0.01) (0.07) y.., 0.1 “ 0.24 0.06 " 0.24 -0.003 0.22 “ (0.04) (0.22) (0.03) (0.21) (0.01) (0.09) r 687 161 526 162 200 325 R2 0.11 0.05 0.2 0.05 | 0.14 | 0.34 F..=o 14.06 | 7. 0.45 7 0.45 72 0.89 R,,.,, 0.11 0.14 0.16 Skewness 10.72 10.61 10.81 Kurtosis 159.07 157.21 162.93 0,, 13.35 8.98 4.62 0‘... 0.12 0.13 0.14 1" Full period of 10 April, 2001 through 31 December, 2003. m Numbers in parathesis are heteroscedasticity adjusted standard errors “’ Fw=0 tests overall significance except the constant "1 denotes 10% significance level 1' ’ denotes 5% significance level (..., denotes 1% significance level yt = xtfll-K'h 5 77) + 10.321015 777 S 72) + 157163-1071?- 72) + 87 where I(.) is the indicator function, and 6, =(6,-06,-1 ...... 6,7,) , i =1,2,3. 95 Table 3.6 Least Square Estimation of Conditional Variance Free Float Period (April, 10 2001- December,31 2003) Variable Estimate Standard Error Constant 0.760 0.430 Dev(5)..,2 -0003 0.020 Dev(25)...2 -0001 0.002 Vol.4: .0001 0.001 y...2 0.010 0.002 m’ 0.001 0.002 y,_32 0.003 0.002 F-Test 0.11 (p-value) 0.99 96 With the two-regime model, the optimal threshold variable is estimated to be 0',_,2 and the estimate of the threshold variable is 0.45. This threshold indicates that the strongest non-linearity exists in the central bank‘s reaction function when there is volatility. This supports the claim that the central bank is more sensitive to volatility in a flee float regime. Most of the observations are in regime two. The coefficient of a,_,2 is significant at a 1% level in this regime. This indicates that central bank‘s intervention is against the volatility when the volatility is greater than the threshold variable. This indicates that the central bank is more responsive to high levels of volatility in a flee float regime. Similar to the two regime model, the coefficent of 0',_,2 is significant at a 1% level in regime three. This result supports the finding in two-regime model such that central bank is more responsive to high levels of volatility. 97 3.4 Conclusion The empirical evidence flom the threshold model gives consistent results with the policies implemented by the central bank during the period investigated. For a managed float period, we reject both the two regime and three regime model. The linear models give that deviation flom the 5 days moving average and recent interventions matter but not the volatility. For a free float period, under the assumption of homoscedastic errors, we fail to accept linearity against the two regime model and both volatility and recent interventions matter. These findings are consistent with the announcement of the CBRT such that the aim is not to affect the level of the exchange rate but rather the excess volatility. 98 CHAPTER 4 Risk Premium and Central Bank Intervention 4.1 Introduction There has been an enormous amount of literature concerning the effects of intervention on currency markets and the motivations for such interventions. These results are mixed and depend on which exchange rate is analyzed , what sample period is studied and also what intervention strategy is followed. There is empirical evidence that indicates that some types of intervention can affect the risk premium in forward markets. However, the risk premium is not necessarily the intended target of the intervention . The Forward exchange rate is a contractual exchange rate established at the time of a transaction that will take place at the maturity time t+l and usually is regarded as the unbiased predictor of the future spot exchange rate. Contrary to popular theory, empirical evidence shows that the forward rate is a biased predictor of the future spot rate and/or is evidence of a risk premium. See Hansen and Hodrick (1980), Hakkio (1981), Baillie et al.(1983), and Baillie (1989). The forward premium anomaly, where the currency of the country with the higher rate of interest is more likely to appreciate than depreciate, is generally r egarded a s o ne 0 f t he m ost important u nresolved p aradoxes in international 99 finance. Numerous explanations have been proposed to explain the forward premium anomaly, but, to date, no one has been able to fully explain the available empirical evidence. See Evans and Lewis (1995), Karninsky (1993), Lewis(1988) Frankel and Froot (1987), Lewis (1989), Elliot and Ito (1995). In a study by Bailie and Osterberg (1997a), Hodrick’s model (Hodrick, 1989) is extended to allow central bank intervention to have a direct effect on the risk premium. Baillie and Osterberg (1997a) find that purchases of US dollars by the Federal Reserve Bank appear to significantly increase the excess dollar denominated returns for both the DM-S and the Yen-S markets. Consistent with this study, Baillie and Osterberg (2000) found that the intervention variables affect the risk premium in an analysis where the relationship between daily deviations flom uncovered interest rate parity and intervention are investigated by using daily overnight euro-currency deposit rates. Central Banks use intervention as a policy instrument. Despite its flequent use, intervention continues to be debated as a policy tool due to the controversy over whether it can achieve the policy goals of either changing the level of nominal exchange rates or reducing its volatility. In studies investigating the impact of intervention directly on the levels of exchange rates, it has generally been found that either intervention has no significant effect or that its outcomes are the opposite of those intended. In the first chapter of this study, the effect of intervention on spot exchange markets is discussed in detail as well as an empirical analysis of the Turkish spot market. This chapter aims to investigate the effect of intervention on risk premium and to asses whether intervention 100 helps to explain the forward premium anomaly, as found by Baille and Osterberg (1997, 2000). The analysis is done for Turkish economy, where the economy is small and has high inflation. Section 4.2 describes the details of the model, Section 4.3 gives the data, Section 4.4 presents the estimation output and Section 4.5 discusses the results. 4.2 Details of the model: Risk Premium and Intervention The Covered Interest Rate Parity Condition tells us the relationship between spot rates, forward rates and interest rates. 05,: —st+1> =0, -.1, 1 (44) s, and f,, corresponds to logarithmic values of spot and forward exchange rates, respectively. Also i,, denotes the domestic currency return on an l-period risk flee dollar bond, denominated in terms of domestic currency where as i 3,1 is the foreign currency return on a risk flee bond denominated in terms of the foreign currency. It implies that the country with the higher rate of interest has experienced an expected depreciation of currency. Sometimes, the relationship between forward rates and future spot rates is simply expressed in terms of the forward rate as being an unbiased predictor of the future spot exchange rate and is given by ft,l:EtSt+[ (4.2) 101 where s,,, is the logarithm of the spot exchange rate and f,, is the logarithm of the forward rate for maturity in time t+l. This is widely rejected by the empirical studies. See Hansen and Hodrick (1980), Hakkio (1981), Baillie et a1. (1983), Baillie (1989). This has led to a type of model as in ft,I = EtSt+1 + 72: (4.3) where p, is a time dependent risk premium. The dependent variable in this study is the difference between expected rate of appreciation of the US dollar and the forward premium or in other words risk premium, which is defined as (Sm, - 8). Note that * (St+k — St) — (it ‘it )= St+k — St - (ft ‘57) = St+k ‘ ft (4-4) Hence, (4+1. -n>=pt +4.7. <45) where um, is the rational expectations error associated with using the forward rate to predict the spot rate k periods and u, is serially uncorrelated for lags greater than k, so E(utu,+h) = 0 for h > k. This restriction is consistent with u,, following a moving average process of order k-l . Baillie and Osterberg (1997a) extend Hodrick’s 1989 model based on a consumption based asset pricing model, where risk premium depends on the conditional variance of 102 production, money growth rates, consumption’s share of production and intervention variables. -aa 2—a 24+ 2—a0' 2*+ 2— 2*+ar —ar*(46) pt' 1 yt 20y! “300! 4 Q: “5%, “60;, 7ft 81 ° where 0' 2 and 09,2 are the conditional variances of logarithms of production and the yt gross grth rate of the currency, respectively. The variable 0'92 denotes the conditional variance of the share of the currency used for intervention. The intervention variable 7, = M ' /M , which is defined as the share of currency held by a foreign govermnent for intervention Operations. Astericks denote foreign country equivalents. The difference between this and Hodrick’s model is the addition of the conditional means and variances of the two intervention variables in the risk premium. The model does not impose any restrictions on w hether o r 11 ot sterilization o ccurs. The m odel is e stimated flom daily data in order to determine the relatively short-lived effect of intervention on risk premium. Hence it is not possible to include the variances of production, money growth rates, and foreign currency holdings as a proportion of money stock. The spot exchange rate, the forward exchange and the intervention variables, which are all observed daily , are the variables included in the estimated model. Hence the risk premium p, in (4.6) is considered to be determined by (SH-k -ft) = 8t '1' . z 61.81“]. + b0 '1’ blUStb + szStS (4.7) 7:1,21 5t = 2,0', (4.8) 0,2 =co+a6',_12 +6a,_12 (4.9) 103 The first two terms on the right hand side of Eq (4.7) corresponds to u, and 8, is a serially uncorrelated white noise process, and 0,- are the moving average parameters. The explanatory variables, US,b,US,s include the intervention variables. Conditional variance in equation (4.10) is represented by a linear GARCH (1 ,1) process. Bollerslev (1986) introduced the GARCH(Generalized Autoregressive Conditional 2 Heteroscedasticity ) process, which extends the ARCH model to make 0', a function of lagged values of 0,2 as well as the lagged values of 8,2 . Bollerslev (1986) required all the coefficients to be positive to ensure that the conditional variance is never negative. The quasi-maximum likelihood estimation is used. 4.3 Data In this study, the data is provided by the Central Bank of Turkey, the Istanbul Stock Exchange and Federal Reserve Bank Board of Governors. The November 1993 through December 2002 data sample consists of daily spot offer rates, interbank ovemight interest rates, treasury bill rates, 30-day euro dollar rates and daily intervention variables. Intervention values are millions of US dollars. This study uses the daily amount of net dollar purchases (sales), daily spot offer rates and interest rates. The analysis separately covers both the managed float and flee float period in terms of exchange rate regime. The development of a firtures market is very new to the Turkish Economy. The forward exchange rate is calculated. The implied forward rate12 is ' 360-day is assumed as the basis for interest quoations instead of 365, see Grabbe (1996). 2 The Implied Forward Rate is calculated as given in Grabbe (1996). 104 30 36000 30 )) 36000 S,(1+i'r( )) F130 - (4.11) (1+i,( where F,30 is the daily 30-day forward rate, S, is the daily spot rate as H USD , see Figure 4.1 and Figure 4.2. i '7 is a proxy the 30 day treasury-bill interest rates for Turkey. Daily interest rates for treasury bills traded in the secondary market is obtained flom the Istanbul Stock Exchange. The interest rate of which the treasury bill has the closest maturity to 30 days is chosen for each day. i, is a proxy for 30-day euro dollar rates. 105 j-l-l 1.11 mam—=6 AL u mega—é Hun—55mm wane Hfiam—v 5 H Ncccccc A? Hmccccc.%lliiilllitilt Hcccccc lilililliiiliill. _ Heeceec uneeece 11: _ Heeeecc 1111111- mccccc cccccc accccc Mccccc l . W v k fl._s._1_7-__l__ hi ~...in__.__i~_ m” a 6 WWW m 6 mm AJ Cam—w. adieu—... was en dram—c mun—5:5“ Em 3:312— en — 2365—3... 58 9.6:”.— E coco—=56... was. 106 7 mam—=6 Ab u maven Hue—.350 Wane HEW—vac Hmccccc Hmeeeee Heeeeee - _ -eeeee Hcccccc 111: mccccc L1 .1 , 11 cccccc 11|1, - \t\SlL occccc 1111- Nccccc cLlllni 6. a e a 6. m m m a m M m m m -W ”M m mm 107 AJ Cam—w. mg» ”a? 3. cutaway man—5:5“ =3 3: 6612— 3. w 232.52.. 58 93:“: u— coon—.52.. was. In this study, the forward rate quotations are matched with the future spot rate so that both represent contracts that would be delivered on the same day. The details of settlement procedures in the spot and forward markets are discussed in detail by Rich] and Rodriquez (1977). The important aspect here is the number of working days in the contract period varies. One reason is that delivery delays often occur around the first of the month. Contracts also are not settled on weekends or on holidays in either of the two countries for a given exchange rate . This exact matching reveals that for the data used in this study, k, the number of working days flom the day of the forward quote to the time of settlement in the spot market varies flom 20 to 26. Since the most common value of k in our sample is 22, u,, the forecast error is estimated as an MA(21) process. This analysis has been done for two sub-periods due to the difference in economic policies. The first sub-period covers between August 1, 1994 and November 30, 1999. and the second one between February 22, 2001 and December 31, 2002. The forecast error for two sub-periods are shown in Figure 4.3 and in Figure 4.4 108 j lac—.6 Pu" magma 33 40.6086» 62.018 m Pom 1i- -- 111- -- _ -w -. i --1, 1c.N_21- - i --.. _WM mxmmmmmmmmmmm memmmMmmMWMMMQ. AJ Cam—w. mega...— 2—8 3393 2.3.. on dram—v man—5E5 c.» 3: 1612— 3. — cram—5.. 5?. 93am—— uc 236532.. See. 109 U PNM . 98 w ...— L Pam ..cbm ue. — u? H m LVN IPNM _ _ e M Z W I M M W M I Feb-01 r-01 [it AJ Cum—w. want»:— 38 3.62—ma 2.3.. a. dram—v nan—=35“ :5 3: 3.32. 3. 3 £335. 33 935: H: USoEra—wuccu. 110 4.4 Estimation Output The details of the estimated model from the daily risk —premium and intervention data are given in Table 4.1 and Table 4.2. The model possess estimated moving average coefficients that approximately decline linearly with the lag. Diagnostic testing of the model fails to provide evidence for a higher order moving average process. Also a linear GARCH (1,1) process is found to be an adequate representation of the conditional second moments for the managed float period and a linear integrated GARCH (1,1) is adequate for free float period. The most interesting aspects of the estimated models in Tables 4.1 and 4.2 concern the coefficients of the variables associated with intervention. In particular, unlike Baillie and Osterberg (1997a) , both purchases and sales of US dollars by the Central Bank of Turkey appear to have no effect on the size of risk premium for TL/USD for the free float period. Similar results are found for the managed float period but the buying of US dollars appear to have significant effect at a 20 percent significance level. This finding is expected to b e the r esult o f h igh inflation in T urkish E conomy. E fforts of d isinflation were not successful through 1990s and stability in the foreign exchange market was uncommon. Under these circumstances, factors affecting the interest rates are related to stability in both the domestic market and government debt management. The Central Bank of Turkey aimed at achieving stability in the markets. Under these circumstances, no relation is expected between risk premium and intervention. 111 Table 4.1: Estimation of Intervention/Risk Premium Model: TL/S “0 Conditional Mean Parameters Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error Do 0-0 0.01 0-0 0.004 mus") 0.0 0.0002 bz(US‘) 0,0 0.0001 91 0.9 0.04 0.9 0.055 02 0.7 0.07 0.7 0.062 03 0-7 0.12 0.7 0.098 04 0.7 0.14 0.7 0.121 95 0-7 0.13 0.7 0.11 06 0.7 0.11 0.7 0.108 07 0.6 0.08 0.6 0.078 0. 0.5 0.06 0.5 0.065 09 0.6 0.05 0.6 0.059 9m 0.6 0.05 0.6 0.058 911 0.5 0.07 0.5 “ 0.075 912 0.5 0.06 0.5 ” 0.065 013 0.4 0.06 0.4 0.063 914 0.5 0.06 0.5 0.064 015 0.4 0.06 0.4 0.059 0m 0.3 0.06 0.3 ‘ 0.064 0n 0.2 0.05 0.2 0.058 01; 0.2 0.05 0.2 0.058 919 0.2 0.05 0.2 0.056 920 0.2 0.05 0.2 0.049 ”21 0-1 0.0;; 0-1 " 0.042 Conditional Variance Parameters to 0.0 0.0 0.0 ' 0.0 a 0.3 0.1 0.3 " 0.1 p 0.6 " 0.1 0.6 0.1 Skewness l .07 1 .00 Kurtosis 23.34 22.45 Q20 24.20 22.44 oz; 13.36 13.23 T 1347 1347 m Full period of 1 August, 1994 through 30 November, 1999. 1') denotes 10% significance level (..) denotes 5% significance level (..., denotes 1% significance level S (s... -f.) = a, + z 19 jg,_ j + b0 +b1US,b + bZUS, j=l,21 2 2 2 a, =w+aa,_1 +fla,_1 is iid (0,1) 8t =Zt0't With zt 112 Table 4.2: Estimation of Intervention/Risk Premium Model: TL/S ‘" Conditional Mean Parameters Coefficient Standard Erron Coefficient Standard Error bo ~0-O35 " 0.016 -0.03 '° 0.016 b,(US") 0.00 0.0007 b2(US') 0.00 0.0014 Or 0.99 0.058 0.99 0.060 02 0.80 0.067 . 0.80 0.068 03 0.83 0.081 0.85 0.081 04 0-70 0.083 0.70 0.082 05 0.75 0.085 0.76 0.088 06 0.74 0.092 0.75 0.097 07 0.70 0.096 0.70 0.100 0a 0.65 0.096 0.66 0.099 09 0.75 0.086 0.75 0.092 9m 0.87 0.081 0.87 0.079 0n 0.76 0.067 0.77 0.069 912 0.76 0.076 0.77 0.082 013 0.79 0.087 0.80 0.085 014 0.68 0.063 0.67 0.063 915 0.66 0.078 0.68 0.083 9.6 0.61 0.082 0.60 0.081 0n 0.56 0.090 0.55 0.086 01. 0.61 0.093 0.62 0.095 919 0.41 0.099 0.40 0.099 920 0.45 0.101 0.45 0.093 ”21 0-26 0.073 0-27 0.072 Conditional Variance Parameters (o m 0.00 €7.60 0.00 a p 0.13 " 0.061 0.13 " 0.061 Skewness -0.33 -0.3 1 Kurtosis 5.71 5.64 02., 14.39 15.63 020’ 13.19 13.16 T 467 467 ('0 Full period of 22 February, 2001 through 31 December, 2002. (0 denotes 10% significance level 0'" denotes 5% significance level (...) denotes 1% significance level (51+k 'ft) = at + Z 6j£t_j 'i' b0 4' bIUStb + bZUStS j=1,21 2 2 2 a, = a) + a£,_1 + ,BO',_1 gtzzta't with Zt is iid (0,1) 113 4.5 Conclusion This chapter is concerned with the relation between the risk premium and central bank intervention. Forward rates are calculated for the Turkish Lira-USS exchange market and then the effect of central bank intervention on the risk premium is presented. Using high quality daily intervention data from the Central Bank of Turkey as well as implied forward rates, an MA(21)-GARCH(1,1) model is estimated. Both purchases and sales of US dollars by the Central Bank of Turkey appear to have no effect on the size of risk premium for TL/USD for the free float period. Similar results are found for the managed float period. No empirical support is found for the theoretical model, with intervention having a significant effect on the risk premium. 114 CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSION This dissertation provides an econometric analysis of the effects of and motivation for central bank intervention in Turkey during the period 1993 - 2003. In the first chapter, we investigate the e ffect of intervention on both the level and volatility of spot returns in Turkey. It is a common belief among policy-makers that central bank intervention is effective. However, the empirical evidence is mixed, and indeed, tends to suggest ineffectiveness overall. In this dissertation, we add to the existing empirical evidence, and find that central bank intervention is not effective in the Turkish foreign exchange market during the period November 1St 1993 until December 31St 2003. We estimate a linear GARCH( 1,1) model for different sub-periods including and excluding the crisis periods. The results show that intervention does not affect the level of spot retm'ns both in the managed and free float regime except during the sub-period January 1St 2000 - February 21st 2001. While intervention has no effect on volatility in the managed float regime, it increases volatility in a free float regime. With respect to the effect of the short-term interest rate, an increase in overnight interest rates appreciates the US dollar in a managed float regime but has no effect in a free float regime. The second chapter investigates the motivation for central bank intervention. We estimate the reaction function for both the managed float and free float regimes separately. The central bank intervention reaction function is estimated using probit, tobit models and then using the censored least absolute deviation method. The empirical 115 evidence gives different results for different regimes. First we estimated a probit model for a managed float and find that the probability of selling the US dollar is increased by the deviation from both the short and the medium term. The probability of a purchase, on the other hand, is increased by the deviation from the long-term. Finally, the probability of intervention is not determined by the conditional volatility for the managed float. Our tobit estimates give similar results. In contrast to a managed float, both our tobit and probit estimates suggest that the central bank is more responsive to volatility during a free float regime. While the sale of the US dollar is determined by volatility and the deviation from the long-term, its purchase is determined by the deviation from the short and medium term. When non-normality and heteroscedasticity in the tobit results are found, all the reaction functions are estimated using the CLAD method so that we get asymptotically normal and consistent estimators. For a free-float regime, we find that neither the deviation from the 5, 50 and 125 days moving average values nor volatility have any effect on the sales of the US dollar. In all of the estimations, the common finding is that the lagged v alue o f i ntervention increases the n ext d ay intervention for both a managed and free float regime. Chapter three examines the intervention reaction fimction using the Threshold model in the non-linear estimation of the reaction function. For a managed float period, we fail to accept both the two regime and three regime model. The linear models give that deviation from the 5 days moving average and recent interventions matter but that volatility does not. For a free float period, under the assumption of homoscedastic errors, we fail to accept linearity against the two regime model and both volatility and recent 116 interventions matter. These findings are consistent with the announced intention of the CBRT not to affect the level of the exchange rate but rather the excess volatility. Chapter four is concerned with the relation between the risk premium and central bank intervention. Forward rates are calculated for the Turkish Lira-USS exchange market and then the effect of central bank intervention on the risk premium is presented. Using high quality daily intervention data from the Central Bank of Turkey as well as implied forward rates, an MA(21)-GARCH(1,1) model is estimated. Both purchases and sales of US dollars by the Central Bank of Turkey appear to have no effect on the size of the risk premium for TL/USD for the free float period. Similar results are found for the managed float period No empirical support is found for the theoretical model, with intervention having a significant effect on the risk premium. 117 REFERENCES Almekinders, G. and Eij ffinger, S. (1996), “A friction model of daily Bundesbank and Federal Reserve intervention”, Journal of Banking and Finance 20, 1365-1380. Almekinders, 6.]. (1995), Foreign Exchange Intervention, Theory and Evidence, Elgar Hants:UK. Baillie, R.T., Lippens, RE. and McMahon, P.C.(1983), “Testing rational expectations and efficiency in the foreign exchange market”, Econometrica 51, 553-563. Baillie, RT (1989), “Econometric tests of rationality and market efficiency”, Econometric Reviews 8, 151-186. Baillie, R.T., Bollerslev, T. and Mikkelsen, H0. (1996), “Fractionally integrated generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity”, Journal of Econometrics 74, 3-30. Baillie, RT. and Osterberg, W.P. ( 1997a), “Central bank intervention and risk in the forward market”, Journal of International Economics 43, 483-497. Baillie, RT. and Osterberg, W.P. (1997b), “Why do central banks intervene?”, Journal of International Money and Finance 16, 909-919. Baillie, R.T., Humpage, CF. and Osterberg,W.P. (2000), “Intervention from an information perspective”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 10, 407-421. Baillie, R.T. and Osterberg, W.P. (2000), “Deviations from daily uncovered interest rate parity and the role of intervention”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 10, 363-379. Beine, M., Benassy-Quere, A. and Lecourt, C. (2002), “Central bank intervention and foreign exchange rates; new evidence from F IGARCH estimations”, Journal of International Money and Finance 21 , 115-144. Bonser-Neal, C. and Tanner, G. (1996), “Central bank intervention and the volatility of the foreign exchange rates: evidence from the options market”, Journal of International Money and Finance 15, 853-878. 118 Bollerslev, T. (1986), “Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity”, Journal of Econometrics, 31, 307-27. Buchinsky, M. (1994), “Changes in the US wage structure 1963-1987: An application of quantile regression.”Econometrica 62, 405-58. Chang, Y. and Taylor, ST. (1998), “Intraday effects of foreign exchange intervention by the Bank of Japan”, Journal of International Money and Finance 17, 191-210. de Jong, R.M. and Herrera, A.M. (2004), “Dynamic censored regression on the open market desk reaction function”, (unpublished manuscript). de Jong, R.M. and Woutersen, T.M. (2004), “Dynamic time series binary choice”, (unpublished manuscript). Domac, I. and Mendoza, A. (2004) “Is there room for foreign exchange interventions under an inflation targeting framework?”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 3288. Dominquez, KM. (1990), “Market responses to coordinated central bank intervention”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy 32, 121-64. Dominquez, K. M. and Frankel, J.A. (1993), “Does foreign exchange intervention matter? The Portfolio effect”, American Economic Review 83, 1356-1369. Dominquez, KM. (1998), “Central bank intervention and exchange rate volatility”, Journal of International Money and Finance 17, 161-190. Dominquez, KM. (2003), “When do central bank interventions influence intra-daily and longer-term exchange rate movements?”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 9875. Edison, H. (1993), “The effectiveness of central bank intervention: a survey of the literature after 1982”, Princeton University, Special Papers in International Economics, No. 18. Eij ffinger, S.C.W. and Gruijters, A.P.D. (1998), “On the short term objectiveness of daily intervention by the Deutsche Bundesbanj and the federal reserve system in the US. Dollar-Deutsche Mark exchange market”, in S.C.W. Eij ffinger, ed., Foreign Exchange Intervention: Obiectivesfi and Effectiveness, Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham. Eij ffinger, S. (1998), “The Ineffectiveness of central bank intervention”, in S.C.W.Eij ffinger, ed., Foreigi Exchgge Intervention: Obiectives and Effectiveness”, Edward Elgar Publishinngheltenham, 401-420. 119 Elliot, G. and Ito, T. (1995), “Heterogeneous expectations and tests of rationality in the US Dollar/Y en forward foreign exchange rate market”, Working Paper, Department of Economics, UC-San Diego. Emir,O., Karasoy, A. and Kunter, K. (2000), “Monetary policy reaction function in Turkey”, Research Department Working Paper, The Central bank of the Republic of Turkey. Evans, MD. and Lewis, K.K. (1995), “Do long term swings in the dollar affect estimates of the risk premia?”, Review of Financial Studies 8, 709-742. Fatum, R. and Hutchison, M.M. (2003), “Is sterilized foreign exchange intervention effective after all? An event study approach”, The Economic Journal 113, 390-411. Frankel, J .A and Froot, K.A. (1987), “Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations”, American Economic Review 77, 133-153. Frenkel, M., Pierdzioch, C. and Stadtrnann, G. (2003), “Modeling coordinated foreign exchange market interventions: The case of the Japanese and US interventions in the 1990s”, Review of World Economics 139(4), 709-29. Frenkel, M. and Stadtrnann, G. (2001), “Intervention reaction functions in the Dollar- Deutshmark market”, Swiss Society for Financial Market Research 15, 328-343. Galati, G. and Melick,W. (1999), “Perceived central bank intervention and market expectations: an empirical study of the Yen-Dollar exchange rate”, BIS working paper 77. Geert, J .A. and Eij ffinger, S.C.W. (1994), “The ineffectiveness of central bank intervention”, Center Discussion Paper Series, T ilburg University, No.94101, December, 1-18. Ghosh, A. (1992), “Is it signaling? Exchange intervention and the Dollar-Deutshemark rate”, Journal of International Economics 32, 201 -220. Gumus, I. (2001), “Effects of the interest rate defense on exchange rates during the 1994 crisis”, Research Department Working Paper, The Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey 14, 1-17. Grabbe, J .O. (1996), Intergtional Financial Markets, Third Edition, Prentice-HallzNew York. Hakkio, C. S. (1981), “Expectations and the forward exchange rate”, International Economic Review 22, 663-678. 120 Hansen, LP. and Hodrick, R.J. (1980), “Forward exchange rates as optimal predictors of future spot rates”, Journal of Political Economy 88, 829-853. Hodrick, RT. (1989), “Risk, uncertainty and exchange rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics 23, 433-459. Hansen, BE. (1997), “Inference in TAR models”, Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 2, 1-14. Hansen, BE. (1999), “Testing for linearity”, Journal of Economic Surveys 13, 551-576. Hansen, BE. (2000), “Sample splitting and threshold estimation”, Econometrica 68, 575- 603. Humpage, OF. (1988), “Intervention and the dollar’s decline”, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Econ. Rev. 3, 2-10. Humpage, OR (1999), “US intervention: assessing the probability of success”, Journal of Money and Credit Bank 31, 731-747. Humpage, OF. (2003), “Government intervention in the foreign exchange market”, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper Series No. 03-15. Hung, J. H. (1997), “Intervention strategies and exchange rate volatility : a noise trading perspective”, Journal of International Money and Finance 16, 779-793. Hutchison, M.M. (2003), “Intervention and exchange rate stabilization policy in developing countries”, International Finance 6, 109-127. Ito, T. (2002), “Is foreign exchange intervention effective? The Japanese experiences in the 1990s”, NBER Working Paper Series, 8914. Ito, T. and Yabu, T. (2004), “What promotes Japan to intervene in the Forex market? A new approach to a reaction function”, NBER Working Paper Series, April 2004. Jun, J. (2004), “Nonlinearity in central bank intervention in the DM/USD market” (Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University). Kaminsky, G. (1993), “Is there a Peso problem? Evidence from the Dollar/Pound exchange rate”, American Economic Review 83, 450-472. Khan, S., and Powell, J .L. ( 2001), “Two-step estimation of semiparametric censored regression models”, Journal of Econometrics 103, 73-110. 121 Kim, S. and Sheen, J. (2002), “The determinants of foreign exchange intervention by central banks: evidence from Australia”, Journal of International Money and Finance 21, 619-649. King, R.M. (2003), “Effective foreign exchange intervention: Matching strategies with objectives”, International Finance 6, 249-271. Leahy, M.P. (1995), “The profitability of US intervention in the foreign exchange markets”, Journal of International Money and Finance 14, 823-844. Lewis, K.K. (1988), ”Testing the portfolio balance model: A multi-lateral approach”, Journal of International Economics 24(1-2), 109-127. Lewis, K.K. (1989), “The persistence of the Peso problem when policy is noisy”, Journal of International Money and Finance 7, 1-11. LeBaron, B.(1999), “Technical trading rule profitability and foreign exchange intervention”, Journal of International Economics 49, 125-143. McKenzie, M. (2004), “An empirical examination of the relationship between central bank intervention and exchange rate volatility : Some Australian evidence”, Australian Economic Papers 43, 59-74. Neeley, C. J. (1998), “Technical analysis and the profitability of the US foreign exchange intervention”, FED St. Louis Review July / August, 3-17. Obstfeld, M.(1989), “The effectiveness of foreign exchange intervention”, NBER working paper 2796. Ozatay, F. (1994), “The Lessons from the 1994 crisis in Turkey: Public debt (mis)management and confidence crisis”, Yapi Kredi Economic Review 7, 21-37. Ozatay, F. and Sak, G. (2002), “The financial crisis in Turkey”, Central Bank of Turkey and Ankara University, 1-29. Popper, H. and Montgomery, J. (2001), “Information sharing and central bank intervention in the foreign exchange market”, Journal of International Economics 55, 295-316. Pagan, A. and Vella, F. (1989), “Diagnostic tests for models based on individual data: A survey”, Journal of Applied Econometrics 4, $29-$59. Powell, J .L. (1984), “Least absolute deviations estimation for the censored regression model”, Journal of Econometrics 25, 303-325. Riehl, H. and Rodriguez, R. (1977), Foreign Exchange Markets, McGraw HillzNew York. 122 Rogers, J. and Siklos, P. (2003), “Foreign exchange market intervention in two small open economies: The Canadian and Australian experience”, Journal of International Money and Finance 22, 393-416. Saacke, P. (2002), “Technical analysis and the effectiveness of central bank intervention”, Journal of International Money and Finance 21, 459-479. Samo, L. and Taylor, M.P. (2001), “Official intervention in the foreign exchange market: Is it effective, and, if so, how does it work?”, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper, No.2690. Schwartz, J. A. (2000), “The rise and fall of foreign exchange market intervention”. NBER Working Paper Series, No. 7751 Sweeney, R..J. (1997), “Do central banks lose on foreign exchange intervention?”, Journal of Banking and Finance 21 , 1667-1684. Vitale, P. (1999), “Sterilized central bank intervention in the foreign exchange market”, Journal of International Economics 49, 245-267. Wooldridge, J .M. (2000), “Introductory econometrics: A modern approach”, South-Western College Publishinngincinnati. Wooldridge, J .M. (2002), “Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data”, CambridgezMIT Press. Yeldan, E. (2001), “On the IMF-directed disinflation program in Turkey: A program for stabilization and austerity or a recipe for impoverishments and financial chaos?”, Bilkent University:Turkey. 123 I!!! “ ‘ .... 111 ts Mu’mrmu 5.7:. 11311111 1293 02