. fiwisu v A . u z “W . a; T251. ...u . z . . fi%.. .Il. - L-UI.IL.>" 11":2.‘ <0l’tQ.‘.fVI-Hl§vfu.fi'r.f This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Household Consumption and Labor Supply Response to Economic Shocks in Russia presented by Ren Mu has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Doctoral degree in Economics SJ? 7 0200 6% Date MSU is an Affirmative ActiorVEqual Opportunity Institution PLACE lN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before dat e due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE will”? 20 210er 6/01 cJClRCIDatoDuopes-sz HOUSEHOLD CONSUMPTION AND LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSE TO ECONOMIC SHOCKS IN RUSSIA By Ren Mu A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2004 ABSTRACT HOUSEHOLD CONSUMPTION AND LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSE TO ECONOMIC SHOCKS IN RUSSIA By Ren Mu This dissertation consists of three chapters. The first two chapters are empirical studies on household consumption and labor supply response to economic shocks, using the data from the Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS). The third chapter studies the econometric estimation methods in an unevenly spaced panel data. Chapter 1. ”Risk, Consumption, Wealth and Human Capital: Evidence from Russia”. This paper investigates Russian households’ consumption response to the income shocks. In particular, this paper examines the effects of education and wealth on the ability of the households to smooth their consumption. A random coefficient model of average treatment effect that allows for endogenous variables is implemented in the estimation. After correcting for the possible sample attrition by the inverse probability-weighting method, this paper finds that consumption is only partially protected from idiosyncratic shocks. The analysis also provides evidence that households in the wealthier group can smooth their consumption better. In addition, education of the household members in the high asset group increases their consumption smoothing ability while no education effect is detected in the low asset group. Chapter 2. ”Multiple Job Holdings As a Way to Smooth Consumption: Labor Response to Wage Arrears Among Russian Couples”. This paper tests the hy- pothesis that labor supply in the form of multiple job holdings was effective in the attempts of households to maintain consumption when their income was declining during the Russian economic transition period. The theoretical framework shows that the possibility of holding secondary job(s) for an individual increases with the possibility of getting wage arrears in their primary job. The paper applies the ”Chamberlain” approach to a dynamic probit model of the decision to hold multiple jobs. It finds that both husbands and wives are more likely to take sec- ondary informal jobs when they have wage arrears shocks in their primary jobs. The combined regression results from the reduced form and structural estimation of households consumption suggest that the insignificant effect of wage arrears on consumption reflect, to certain extent, the adjustment of secondary job holdings. Chapter 3. ”Estimation With or Without Straight Exogeneity Assumption in Unevenly Spaced Panel Data”. This paper studies the econometric estimation methods for unevenly spaced data, which is very common in the survey data con- ducted in developing countries. Classic minimum distance, and one-step GMM estimators are used to impose the non-linear parameter restrictions in dynamic models. The paper also shows that these two methods also can be applied to estimations without strict exogeneity assumption. To Xu and Chengcheng ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I complete this dissertation with a keen awareness of and deepest gratitude for the help and support from many people. I owe a tremendous debt of gratitude to John Strauss, my mentor and major professor. Over the past few years, Professor Strauss has played a substantial role in my academic development and training as an economist. He has always been generous with his time and his knowledge when it comes to my endless questions at different stages of my research. He has never been short of encouragement at times when I had doubts and worries. His guidance has made my graduate study a rewarding experience, one that I can look back upon with fond memories. Most importantly, he has set a model as a scholar, that I will always try to live up to throughout my career. I am also especially thankful to Professor Jeffrey Wooldridge. His art of teach— ing has convinced me of the beauty of applied econometrics. Throughout the undertaking of this dissertation, his valuable suggestions and insights made my task much more interesting and easier. His great books in econometrics will con- tinue to influence my way of thinking about and carrying out economics empirical analysis. I also owe thanks to Professor John Giles and Professor Jeff Biddle. Dr. Giles stimulated my thinking about many of the ideas presented in this dissertation. Equally importantly, I am grateful that he successfully persuaded me five years ago that E. Lansing is a lot better place than Seattle. Dr. Biddle has carefully and critically read different versions of my dissertation drafts. He has offered a number of helpful comments and suggestions at each time of his reading. I am also indebted to Professor Jeffrey Riedinger, who has given me valuable supports in many ways. I enjoyed very much and learned a lot from working for him as a research assistant in the past two years. I would also like to acknowledge a number of professors who have influenced my academic development, including Jack Meyer, David Neumark, John Gooddeeris, Jay Choi, Steven Haider and James Stapleton. I am also thankful for the friendship and encouragement from Professor Christine Amsler. Many incredible fellow graduate students provide the warmth and support throughout my study at MSU. Zhehui, Yanyan, Lebo, Pond, Olena, and Firman are the best friends and colleagues that a person could ever have. Finally, I would like to give a special thanks to my family. My father has always encouraged me to do my best. My sister has never failed to give me loving advices on different issues. My mother is a trustworthy source of strength and wisdom for me. Her help with my baby made it possible for me to focus on my dissertation and finish it. My husband, Xu, has been enthusiastic and effective in solving all my computer-related problems, besides the fact that he is a good listener with great patience and love. Our son, Chengcheng, joined us in our life journey six months ago, and has since motivated me and brought us tremendous joy. In a concrete way, this study is theirs. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ix LIST OF FIGURES xii 1 Risk, Consumption, Wealth and Human Capital: Evidence From Russia 1 1.1 Introduction ............................... 1 1.2 Theoretical Framework and Empirical Implications ......... 6 1.2.1 A Full Consumption Insurance Model ............ 6 1.2.2 Empirical Implications and Test ................ 9 1.3 Data and Descriptive Statistics .................... 12 1.4 Sample Attrition: Evidence and Correction .............. 16 1.5 Endogenous Income Change ...................... 20 1.6 Results .................................. 23 1.7 Conclusions ............................... 29 BIBLIOGRAPHY .............................. 44 APPENDIX .................................. 47 2 Multiple Job Holdings As a Way to Smooth Consumption: Labor Response to Wage Arrears Among Russian Couples 60 2.1 Introduction ............................... 60 2.2 Wage Arrears In Russia ........................ 65 2.2.1 The Causes of Wage Arrears .................. 65 2.2.2 The Distributions of Wage Arrears on the Primary Jobs . . 68 2.3 Theoretical Framework and Empirical Issues ............. 72 2.3.1 Theoretical Framework .................... 72 2.3.2 Empirical Specification ..................... 80 2.4 Data and Summary Statistics ..................... 86 2.4.1 Sample Creation ........................ 86 2.4.2 Summary Statistics ....................... 89 2.5 Empirical Results ............................ 92 2.5.1 Labor Supply Response to Wage Arrears—Secondary Job Holdings and Job Changes ................... 92 2.5.2 Effects of Wage Arrears on Household Consumption ..... 95 2.6 Conclusion ................................ 97 BIBLIOGRAPHY .............................. 124 APPENDIX .................................. 127 3 Estimation With or Without Strict Exogeneity Assumption in Unequally Spaced Panel Data 128 3.1 Introduction ............................... 128 vii 3.2 Estimation Under Strict Exogeneity Condition ............ 131 3.2.1 Static Model ........................... 131 3.2.2 Dynamic Model with Lagged Explanatory Variables ..... 132 3.3 Estimation Without Strict Exogeneity Condition ........... 141 3.3.1 Static Model ........................... 141 3.3.2 Dynamic Model ......................... 142 3.4 Conclusion ................................ 146 BIBLIOGRAPHY .............................. 148 viii List of Tables 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 1.10 1.11 1.12 1.13 Household Real Income and Consumption Change Over Years and Regions ................................. 31 Descriptive Statistics .......................... 32 Coefficient of Variation (CV) in Income and Consumption (per capita) 33 Descriptive Statistics in 1995 by Attrition .............. 34 Attrition Probability during 1995—2000 ................ 35 Predicting the Change of Income ................... 37 Consumption Smoothing for the Whole Sample ........... 38 Consumption Smoothing for the Low Asset Group .......... 40 Consumption Smoothing for the High Asset Group ......... 42 First Stage Regression ......................... 47 Regression Results With vs Without 1994 Data— Low Asset Group 49 Regression Results With vs Without 1994 Data— High Asset Group 51 Consumption Smoothing for Low Asset Group (Without Education Interaction) ............................... 53 ix 1.14 1.15 1.16 1.17 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 2.10 Consumption Smoothing for High Asset Group (Without Education Interaction) ............................... 55 Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group (With Education Interaction; With Attrition Correction) ................ 57 Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group (With Asset In- teraction; With Attrition Correction) ................. 58 Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group(With Education / Assets Interaction; With Attrition Correction) ................ 59 Incidence and Level of Wage Arrears ................. 99 Wage Arrears by Occupation (before/ after 1998) ........... 104 Distribution of Employment States of Husband and Wife ...... 107 Individual and Household Characteristics by Wage Arrears ..... 108 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Holding Secondary Job) to First Time Wage Arrears ................... 110 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Holding Secondary Job) to Wage Arrears .......................... 112 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Holding incidental work) to First Time Wage Arrears ................... 114 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Holding incidental work) to Wage Arrears ......................... 116 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Change of Job) to First Wage Arrears ........................... 118 Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Change of Job) to Wage Arrears .............................. 120 2.11 Consumption Regression (First Time Arrears) ............ 122 2.12 Consumption Regression (Wage Arrears) ............... 123 2.13 First Stage Regression of Multiple Job Holdings ........... 127 xi List of Figures 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 Currently Owed Wage by Age (Men) ................. 100 Currently Owed Wage by Age (Women) ............... 100 Currently Owed Wage by Education (Men) .............. 101 Currently Owed Wage by Education (Women) ............ 101 Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Men) ............... 102 Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Women) .............. 102 Currently Owed Wage by Wage (Men) ................ 103 Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Women) .............. 103 xii Chapter 1 Risk, Consumption, Wealth and Human Capital: Evidence From Russia 1 . 1 Introduction Several years into the economic and social transition in Russia, many households have been in an environment of considerable economic uncertainty. The risk of wage nonpayment to working men and women is pervasive and the incidence of pension denial to retired people is high (Lokshin and Ravallion, 2000; Stillman 2001, Jensen and Richter 2002).1 In 1998, when the Russian government aban- doned its defense of a strong ruble exchange rate against the dollar and defaulted on the government domestic debt, one of the most serious financial crises hit the 1Based on Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS), the wage nonpayment rate in 1994, 1995, 1996, 1998 and 2000 is 38.8%,40.4%, 57%, 59% and 27% respectively. The rate of pension nonpayment in these years is 3.3%,8.4%, 33.3%, 15.1% and 2.7% respectively. economy.2 Two years after that economic shock, there has been substantial in- crease in incomes, but the economic wellbeing of the households has not been fully recovered (Mroz, Henderson and Popkin 2002). Using the data from the Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS), we can clearly see several features in the fluctuations of the households’ income and con- sumption over the years (Table 1.1). Russian households have experienced several years of income decline since 1994.3 In November 1998, three months after the financial crisis, households income per capita dropped by 60% compared to 1994. In 2000, income per capita increased by 24% from 1998 and consumption increased by 19%, but consumption still remains the second lowest since 1994. Moreover, this trend holds true even after geographic variations are controlled (Column 2, 4 of Table 1.1). This paper asks a simple question: in such a tumultuous transition period, how well have Russian households been dealing with their income shocks? Particu- larly, this paper investigates the consumption smoothing ability of the households. Previous research on consumption smoothing in Russia has found limited con- sumption smoothing among households (Stillman 2001). Most of the empirical tests for perfect consumption smoothing in developing countries find real and sig- 2 Official Russian statistics estimate the Russian real GDP contracted 4.6% in 1998. The inflation rate, using the consumer price index, hit 84.4% and the interest rate on treasury bill rose from 27.8% in May 1998 to 135.3% in August 1998. Unemployment rate had reached close to 12% having increased from 7.0% in 1997. See Mroz and Popkin (1999), Cooper (1999). 3The panel data in RLMS has covered 1994, 1995, 1996 1998 and 2000. Russian GDP grew slightly only in 1997 (0.4%), the first case since 1992. See Lokshin and Ravallion (2000) nificant consumption smoothing, that is, for many households consumption does not track household income particularly well regardless of the lack of efficient fi- nancial infrastructure and well-functioning social security, but the studies also re— ject the existence of full consumption insurance (Townsend 1995, Morduch 1995). At the same time, empirical studies have also found that households with differ- ent characteristics respond differently to income shocks. Wealthy households or households with more assets such as land are found to be better insured against income shocks (Townsend 1994, Morduch 1995, Jalan and Ravallion 1999). This paper looks at the potential effect of education on household consumption smooth— ing. The households with high—education members might, for instance, be able to better obtain information and plan their expenditure, thus shielding consumption from short-run fluctuations in individual income. This education effect is particu- larly interesting is because it provides one piece of empirical evidence to test the hypothesis that the ability of to deal successfully with economic disequilibria is enhanced by education.4 Schultz (1975) argues that educated individuals adapt more easily as economic circumstances change, using assets more efficiently, ob- taining better credit arrangements and exploiting new income opportunities more quickly. Under this hypothesis, we expect to see that households with higher lev- els of human capital would have more allocative efficiency and thus do better in 4Welch (1970)stressed that the role of education in production may directly contribute to physical product, which is the “worker effect ”of education. On the other hand, increased education may enhance a worker’s ability to acquire and decode information about costs and productive characteristics of the other inputs. This is “allocative effect ”of education. Schultz (1975) contributes the enhanced ability of dealing with disequilibrium to the “allocative effect of ”education. smoothing their consumption against income shocks.5 The identification of this effect is complicated because education enhances the earning and thus the wealth of the households, and the wealth in turn enhances the consumption smoothing ability of the households. To separate the education effect, which might be over and above the wealth effect, I stratify the sample into two wealth groups. Further, in each wealth group, the impact of income change on consumption is allowed to depend on the maximum education level of adult household members. Due to the endogeneity of income change and the fact that the coefficient of income change on consumption change may differ across households with differing human capital, I implement a two-step method using a random coefficient model following Wooldridge (2002b). At the first step, income changes of the households are predicted by exogenous shocks. The second step involves using the predicted income change and the predicted income change interacted with education variable as instrumental variables to estimate the main effect of income change and the education effect on consumption smoothing. The empirical work in this paper uses data from phase two of the Russian Lon- gitudinal Monitoring Survey (RLMS), for the years 1994, 1995, 1996, 1998 and 2000 (Rounds IV—VIII).6 This survey is designed as a repeated sample of house- 5 Glewwe and Hall (1998) found that households with better educated heads are less vulner- able to macro-economic shocks in Peru. The vulnerability is measured by change in per capita consumption. 6 The regression analysis doesn’t include the 1994 data because the information of years of education of the household members is not available. hold dwellings, not of each household itself. Evidence is found that the households move out and thus attrition from the survey are intrinsically different from the households which remain in the survey. To address this problem, a predicted weight associated with attrition probability is assigned to each household. This inverse probability weighting scheme corrects sample attrition and leads to consis- tent estimators (Wooldridge 2002a; Wooldridge 2002c ) The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the theory of full consumption insurance and its testable implications. Section 3 summarizes the data used to test the hypothesis. The evidence of a possible attrition problem is presented in Section 4 and the inverse probability weighting to correct for attrition is explained. Section 5 discusses the endogeneity of income change and the implementation of the random coefficient model of average treatment effect to estimate the main effect of income change, as well as the interaction of income change and education. Empirical results are discussed in section 6. We find that income changes matter to consumption change, so there is no perfect consumption smoothing. We also find evidence supporting the hypothesis that education of household members enhances the consumption smoothing in the high wealth group but not in the low wealth group. Section 7 concludes the paper. 1.2 Theoretical Framework and Empirical Impli- cations 1.2.1 A Full Consumption Insurance Model The full consumption insurance outcome can be obtained through a risk shar- ing model cast in the setting of a social planner, where the planner maximizes the sum of weighted utilities of individuals subject to an aggregated resource constraint (Mace 1991; Cochrane 1991; Townsend 1994; McCarthy 1995).7 As- sume a single-good economy 8with N households and each of them lasts for T periods. Household i has state contingent time separable utility U (Cf-ASH, 6%)), where Cit is the consumption per capita of household in the state of T at time t ; sTt is the state of the world at time t, 7' = 1,2, ...3; and 6ft is taste shifters of the household 2'. Let 7r(s.rt) denote the subjective prediction about state 7' at time t with 2::1W(31t) = 1, where 7r(sTt) captures the expectation about the uncertainty. So the life time discounted expected utility of household 2' is: U1: = 2:le 2:21 mn(sfi)U(Cft(sTt),6it), where p,- indicates the time dis- count rate of household 2' and 6ft is the taste shifters of household i. If the house- holds are to pool their resources together and insure each other against idiosyn- cratic shocks, this is equivalent to a social planner maximizing a weighted sum of 7Such optimal risk sharing allocation can also be achieved as a competitive equilibrium in a decentralized economy with complete contingent markets (Arrow 1964; Townsend 1994; Deaton 1997) 8The full consumption insurance implications continue to hold for the multiple good economy (Mace 1991). household utilities subject to an overall constraint at each time and in each state of the world. Then the Pareto-optimal consumption allocations can be derived from the planning problem N S T 1 . . Max}: “’2' Z Z fi”(srt)U(Cit(Srti 5ft» (1-1) i=1 T=1t=1( +p‘) N . . s.t. Z@,(57t,6;t)=CA(sTt) 7:1,2,...s;t=1,2,...r. (1.2) i=1 where CA(sTt) is the total amount of the consumption good available at each time t in each state 7; w,- is the weight assigned to household 2' with w,- > 0 and 2,1111),- = 1 for i = 1, 2, ...N. The control variable for the social planner is it, the consumption of household 2' at each time given the state of the world. Take the derivative with respect to Cit: the first-order conditions for the problem maximizing (1.1) subject to (1.2) are: 1 . . wi7f(37t)WUI(Cft(STta63ml) = /\(Srt) (1.3) where /\(Srt) is the Lagrangian multiplier at time t in the state T. Equation (1.3) says that in the optimal resource allocation in a given state of the world, the weighted marginal utilities are equalized across individual households. When the state of T happens, the ca: — post counterpart of (1.3) without any uncertainty is mmv’rdwi» = At (1.4) To remove the fixed effect of each household associated with 11),, divide (1.4) at time t + 1 by (1.4) and we can get U,( f+1(f+1)) 1 =At+1 U'(Cg(5;)) 1+p,- A, (1.5) The right-hand side of equation (1.5) consists only of aggregate variables and it is the same for all households. This equation has the full consumption insurance implication because it says that the growth of discounted marginal utility across all the households in community should be equal and be a function of growth in A, which is a function of growth in total resources available to the community. This model does not imply the reference group of consumption smoothing. The “community ”here can be a village (Towsend 1994), extended households (Al- tonji,Hayashi and Kotlikoff 1992), ethnic lines (Grimard 1997), and asset groups or stratifications of households according to their assets level(McCarthy 1995; J alan and Ravallion 1999). The reference group used in this paper is asset groups within each primary survey unit (PSU).9 9A PSU is identified using the variable “site ”contained in the RLMS and the table made available by the Carolina Population Center. The number of households in each PSU varies from 37 to 172. 1.2.2 Empirical Implications and Test To derive a testable form of (1.5), suppose the utility function is a power utility 10 . . . 1 . water» = €$P(U5i);(ci)a (1.6) Strict concavity requires a < 1.The households have the same constant relative risk aversion, (1 — 0). So I ' 22 2t - U(C_‘2) =e$pa(6t+1-6t)(cli)(l_0) (1.7) U’(Cf+1) C“ Substituting (1.7) into (1.5) and taking the logarithms, we will get the following equation as the test for perfect insurance hypothesis: . . 1 ' - log Ctz+1 — log Ctz = :[Uwf-H _ 6f) /\t 1 +log(1 +Pil+108(—/\f’)l (1-8) Conditional on the change in taste shifters ((52+1 — 5%) and the time discount rate of pi, equation (1.8) implies that in the optimal risk allocation, the consumption growth of each household 2' depend only on the aggregate resource availability vari— ables through At and At“, but doesn’t depend on the individual income growth log Yi — log Yi or initial assets level of the household Ai. Using the above equa- t+1 t 1 tion to test for perfect consumption insurance , we make the following assumptions. 10The specification of power utility directly gives the relationship between growth rate of individual consumption and the aggregate variables. (Mace 1991) First, the change of taste shifter 6:: is a function of the change of household char- acteristics X; such as household size and household composition as well as the household characteristics in the initial period. Discount rate p,- is a function of household head characteristics H: such as age and sex. If the full consumption insurance hypothesis is true within community r, we can include a set of com- munity, year and the interactions of year and community dummies (Dr,Dt and Drt) to control for the community average consumption. 11 Then the testable econometric model of equation (1.8) takes the following form A log C2 = a0 + alA log Yti + 012/42, + a3AX§ + O4Hi + OSDt + OGDr + 07D” + 5i (1.9) If the full consumption insurance exists, then 011 = 0 and (12:0. The test based on (1.9) is under the null hypothesis that there is optimal con- sumption allocations within a complete risk sharing system. But because of moral hazard and incomplete information, such risk sharing systems, even in the village economy, may not be viable regardless of its advantage(Deaton, 1997). In a more realistic setting, the risk sharing among individuals can be obtained through in- formal social networks, the formal credit market, financial markets, and insurance markets. But because incomes covary, it may be that the group is inefficient in producing insurance especially if the shock is large, as was the one in Russia dur- ing this period. Maybe also participation in the risk-sharing system may incur 11Using a set of dummies is preferred to using the changes in community mean consumption. (Deaton (1992), Jalan and Ravallion (1994)) 10 costs and thus not every household is equally likely to participate in this system and thus is not equally insured against idiosyncratic income shocks. For example, liquidity constrained households may not have access to credit market. Likewise, information constrained households are unlikely to participate in the financial mar- ket or even insurance markets if the market entrance imposes information costs. But information costs are lower for better educated people if education helps peo- ple to obtain, process and use information (Welch 1970). Then we should expect that households whose members have high education are more likely to be covered by the risk-sharing systems than households with less-well educated people. This suggests that the coefficient on the income depends on the education level of the household members. If true, we can add in an interaction term of income change and maximum education level of the household members (E‘) into the equation (1.9) and expect to see a negative sign on this interaction term. I use demeaned maximum education (Ef — E) in the interaction term. In this specification, the coefficient of the change in income can be interpreted as the average treatment ef- fect of education on consumption smoothing, that is , the consumption smoothing of the households whose members have average education level. But one problem with this procedure is that the coefficient on the interaction term also captures the wealth effect on consumption smoothing since households with high—educated peOple have higher income earning ability. One possible way to separate this wealth effect of education from the allocative effect of education is to 11 stratify the data by assets. Thus, we estimate the following equation for two asset groups separately: A log CE = a + AA log Y." + M log Y." x (Ei — E) + BaE" + mg + @3sz + + fieHi + ant + aDr + all)... + e: (1.10) 1.3 Data and Descriptive Statistics The data used for this paper come from the Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS), which was conducted by the Population Center at the University of North Carolina. The RLMS is a household-based survey designed to measure the effects of Russian reform on the economic well-being of households and individuals starting from 1992. Beginning in 1994, RLMS was designed to provide a longitudinal study of populations of dwelling units. At each round, the RLMS interview was completed with the household and its members in the original sample dwelling unit. This sampling plan did not call for households to be followed if they moved from the sample dwelling unit. Consequently, the RLMS is not a true panel design. But unique household and individual identification numbers exist in the data and can be used as a link to form a pure panel of the households who remain in the original dwelling unit over time. The detailed information on household-level income and expenditures can then be used to study the economic welfare of households in a 12 dynamic setting. Data on individual wage earnings, pension earnings, complete years of education and employment status are also provided. The data used for analysis are for the years 1994-1996, 1998 and 2000. In the regression analysis containing the interaction term of income change and years of education, we drop the 1994 data because it does not have the information about years of education of the household members although it has information of level of schooling.12 The value of assets is the estimated worth of the non-financial households assets.13 It is used as a proxy for household wealth. The households then are divided into two groups according to their asset levels in 1994. Total household consumption of the household is the sum of expenditures on food consumption and non-food ex- penditures on clothing, fuel, transportation, repair service, laundry, postal service, medical service, marriage/funeral service, rent, child support, schooling, sanato— rium, travel and clubs. The growth of consumption is calculated as the logarithmic difference in consumption. Total household income is the constructed income in RLMS, which is the sum of income from the workplace; fuel subsidies; child sup- port; pensions; asset income and transfer payment from government, relatives or friends. But some components of total income may serve to smooth consumption. For example, transfers (both private and public) may increase after the shocks. 12Regression including the 1994 data is presented in the Appendix. 1994 data contains only the categorical level of education of the household members, so we include three education level dummies in that regression. 13The assets include (1) Refrigerator; (2) Homer; (3) Washing Machine; (4) Black & White TV; (5) Color TV; (6) VCR; (7) Car or Tmck; (8) Motorcycle; (9) 'Il‘actor; (10) Garden Cottage; (11) Dacha or Other House; (12) Other Apartment. Household survey respondent was asked to estimate the current value of their assets based on the age of assets. The missing value is replaced by the reported area-age specific asset. 13 Including endogenous components in the income measure will result in the volatil- ity of income shock being systematically understated (Rosenzweig, 1988; Strauss and Thomas, 1995). Because of this concern, we construct a variable we call net income, which doesn’t include the endogenous components such as unemployment benefits, transfers from relatives , friends, church, mosque, foreign and interna- tional organizations; and incomes from sales and rental of assets. Table 1.2 provides an economic and demographic profile of the sample of 1412 households with 673 households in the low asset group and 739 in the high asset group. Total income is 40.3% higher than net income for the low asset group; for the high asset group, it is 30.21% higher than net income. This large proportion of endogenous components of income indicate that households smooth their income by public and private transfer or assets selling. This justifies our concern over the endogeneity of income change. Thus, we use net income we defined above as a measure of household income in the regression analysis. Households on average have 3.72 members. The number of senior people in the low asset group is 0.786, significantly higher than 0.605 in the high asset group. But the number of children in the high asset group is 0.906, higher than 0.673 in the low asset group. These differences in the household composition between the two assets groups may be due to the fact that households with more senior people have older assets whose estimated values are usually not as high as the assets in the households composed of relatively younger people. 14 Descriptive statistics of the incidence of households that report unemployment, wage arrears and pension arrears are presented in Panel B of Table 1.2. More households in the high asset group report unemployment and wage arrears, but more households in low asset group report pension arrears. They correspond, not surprisingly, to the age differentials between the two groups. Panel C of Table 1.2 presents the proportion of households which experienced fresh spells of unemploy- ment, wage arrears or pension arrears in the month of the survey. For example, about 8.1% of the households have reported at least one household member who was newly unemployed and 8.8% of the households have wage arrears for one month or less but have not experienced wage arrears in the previous year. More house- holds in the low asset group experienced a pension shock than in the high asset group. This may simply be due to the fact that there are more seniors in the households in low assets group. Table 1.3 presents information of the within-household coefficient of variation (CV) of total income, net income and consumption of the households in the analysis sample. The CV at the household level is calculated as the within-household standard deviation divided by the within-household mean. The CV at the group level is the average of CVs of the households in that group. The CV of total income for both assets groups is more than 0.5. Without controlling for endogenous income smoothing, as we expect, the CV for net income is higher and is over 0.6 for both groups. On average, consumption has tighter distribution than the total 15 income. The Kruskal-Wallis rank test confirms that CV of consumption for the lower assets group is significantly larger than that for the high asset group. This is not surprising since we expect that households with more assets experience less volatile changes in their consumption because they can draw on their assets to smooth their consumption. The simple correlation between consumption and net income is also lower for the high asset group although the magnitude is still as big as 0.42. It means that consumption follows income and therefore the ability to smooth consumption is very limited for households in both groups, if we assume that households prefer smooth consumption. 1.4 Sample Attrition: Evidence and Correction Among 3548 households included in the 1995 survey, 2214 of them remain in the survey for four rounds, but 1334 of them dropped out during periods of before the 2000 survey. We call these households leavers. Are the households who remain in the survey (stayers) significantly different from the leavers? Table 1.4 presents the summary statistics by attrition using 1995 data. On average, the stayers are poorer, have a less educated household head, larger household size and more senior members. Fewer stayers live in Moscow and St. Petersburg, rather more of them live in non—urban areas. All these differences between the two samples are statistically significant at 5%. Apparently, the households in our analysis sample, namely the stayers, are not a random sample from the original sample in 1995. 16 Using the stayers in the analysis without correcting for any potential attrition bias may result in overestimating the consumption response to income change, since the stayers are poorer and may face more credit constraint because disproportionably more of them live in non-urban areas. There are two other variables in the data which are closely related to household attrition but may not be correlated with consumption change. They are the assess- ments of the interviewer about the level of cooperation of the household respondent with the survey enumerators. That is, at the end of the survey, the interviewer was asked to assess the respondent’s attitude toward the interview as well as the re- spondent’s behavior during the interview. The attitude was listed as “friendly and interested”; “not particularly interested ”;“impatient and worried ”; and “hostile ” The behavior includes “comfortable”; “occasionally nervous ”; and “nervous ”. On a scale of 1 to 4 with 1 representing the highest degree of cooperation, the mean attitude of the movers is 1.28, while the mean attitude of the stayers is 1.23. The difference is small in magnitude, but statistically significant at 5% level. It means that the households which were more willing to cooperate in the interview were more likely to stay in the survey. Significant differences between the stayers and the movers suggest that estimates that don’t correct for potential attrition appropriately might be inconsistent. We use the inverse probability weighting (IPW) method (Wooldridge 2002a)to correct potential bias from sample attrition. 17 Under the key assumption that sample attrition is ignorable with respect to the consumption growth conditional on the observables in the attrition equation”, the IPW gives more weight to the households which are less likely to stay in the sample to make the analysis sample more representative of the original sample. The IPW procedure involves two stages of estimation. In the first stage, at time t (t=2, 3, 4) an attrition probit model is estimated, restricting attention to those households still in the sample at t — 1. Out of this sample, some are lost to attrition at time t, and some are not. Let aids“ = 1[:r,-t6t+v,-t]|s,-t_1 = 1, s,t_2 = 1, ..., 3,1 = 1), where t=2, 3, 4 and Uitlmz't ~ Normal (0,1), be the probit estimation of the conditional probability of household 2' to stay in the survey at time t. These predicted conditional probabilities can not be used directly in the IPW procedure because the sample at each time period is not representative of the population that was originally sampled at t=1. However, Wooldridge (2002a) shows that the joint probabilities calculated from these predicted conditional probabilities can be used in the IPW procedure and lead to consistent estimators. The predicted conditional probabilities 7i“ (t=2, 3, 4) are used in the second stage to calculate the joint probability that the households stay in the survey for two, three and four rounds. We denote the unconditional probabilities by 15,2, 13,3, 152-4 respectively. We ignore the initial condition and assume that all the households have the same probability of being in the original sample. Then 15,1(sfl = 1) = 7}“ = 1. So the joint probability, 1312(82'1 = 1,812 = 1) = fin X 5B2, 1523(82‘1 = 1; 8r2 = 1:513 = 1) = 14In our case, this means that the selection is not related to the idiosyncratic errors in regression 1.9. Our test confirms this assumption and the coefficient of the lead selection indicator in a fixed effect regression of 1.9 is not significant with a t-statistic being -1.01. 18 fin >< 7E2 X fr2'3; 152210911 = 1,822 = 1,823 = 1,3,4 = 1) = fin X 7h? x 7m X 7m. According to the estimated probability pit, each household 2' at time t is assigned a WBIght wit = l/fiit- Table 1.5 presents the probit estimation of the conditional probabilities of being in the survey for the years 1996, 1998 and 2000. Conditional on the household demographic characteristics, geographic locations as well as respondent’s level of cooperation in the survey, we find that income is no longer significant in explaining probabilities of being in the survey. The age of household head affects the prob- ability in an inverse U shape pattern. For example, ceteris paribus, households with household head at age 50 in 1998 are the most likely to remain in the survey in 2000. The more senior people a household has, the more likely that it is going to remain in the survey. Bigger households are more likely to stay in the survey continuously. Households in the Moscow and St. Petersburg region are more likely to drop out compared to any other region covered by the surveys. The level of cooperation of the household respondent in the oral survey is also positively as- sociated with staying 15 For example, the least cooperative households in 1996 and 1998 are more likely to drop from later surveys. And if the respondent was nervous during 1995 or 1996 survey, then the household is more likely to remain in the survey in 1996 and 1998. The predicted probabilities (frit) from these probit 15Heckman’s solution requires that there be at least one exogenous variable affecting selection that does not appear in the structure equation. By reasonable assumption, the attitude and behavior variables which measure the level of respondent’s cooperation may well serve as such identifying variables. But in the IPW method, no such identifying variables are needed. 19 estimation are then used to calculate the joint probability for each year (p,,)and each household is assigned a weight equal to the reciprocal of the joint probability (wit = 1/152‘tl- 1.5 Endogenous Income Change Net income defined in section 3 is used as household income in our analysis in order to reduce the potential bias from endogenous income smoothing. But two empirical problems still remain. The first problem is the measurement error in income. The measurement error in income will lead to an attenuation bias in the estimate of the coefficient in income growth and thus we will be less likely to reject the complete consumption insurance hypothesis. The second problem is that net income change may still be endogenous. For example, unobservables that affect income change may also affect consumption change. A credit constraint level that the household faces may affect income change as well as the precautionary savings of the households, thus consumption of the households. Also income change may be correlated with unobserved preference shifts (Cochrane 1991). If income change leads to higher preference for leisure and if leisure/ consumption are substitutes, then the estimate of the coefficient of income change on consumption change will be biased downward. In the case that leisure and consumption are complements, we might overestimate the response of the consumption change to income change. 20 In our model, the coefficient of income change on consumption change is also allowed to differ across the households with different human capital. We implement a new method following a random coefficient model of average treatment effect with endogenous variables (Wooldridge 2002b) to estimate equation (1.10). The traditional 2SLS estimator uses interactions of exogenous variables with (Ef — E) as instrumental variables for log I”; x (E — E). This method may result in too many overidentifying restrictions and the 2SLS estimator may have poor finite sample properties (Wooldridge 2002b). The new method involves two steps. First, the change of income is predicted from the estimation of a linear reduced form by regressing income change on exogenous variables. Call this predicted income A A change A log Yti' The second step is to use the predicted income change (A log Yt’) , the interaction of predicted income change with education(A log Y: x E‘) as instrumental variables for A log Y," and Alog Y," x (Ei — E) in equation (1.10). We use two sets of exogenous variables to predict the change of income. First the change of total household wage earnings is used as a predictor for the change in the household income 16. The total wage earnings is constructed separately from individual questionnaires. Each adult in the household reports their total labor earnings in the individual questionnaires. These individual responses can be added up to the household level and form a separate measure of household income. This measure of income also contains measurement error but this error may be 16Stillman(2001) used aggregated individual total income as instrumental variable for house- hold income. 21 uncorrelated with the measurement error in the household total income reported by the household respondent. Household income comes from a separate household questionnaire and the respondent is asked to estimate total household income. Thus the change in this aggregated wage earning can be used as an instrumental variable to purge the measurement error from the total income. But the change of total wage earning can’t account for the potential endogeneity associated with household income change. As an alternative to correct for the endogeneity of income change and also to capture the unexpected nature of idiosyncratic income shocks, a second set of exogenous variables are used. They are: whether there is a household member who is newly owed wage (for no more than one month) 17, whether there is a household member who is newly unemployed, whether there are retired household members who are newly owed pensions, and an interaction of pension arrears with a dummy variable for the year 1996, which was the year of the pension crisis. Table 1.6 presents the estimation of income change in the first step. We can see that the change of wage income obtained from individual questionnaires are significant both statistically and economically in predicating household income change. When we use the shocks of unemployment, wage arrears and pension 17The following survey questions are used to construct this variable. First, “At the present time, does your place of work owe you any money which for some reason they didn’t pay you on time? ”. Second, “For how many months has your enterprise not paid this money to you? ”. If the answer to the first question is “Yes ”and the answer to the second question is “one month ”, I take it as “owed wage for no more than one month ”. The “newly owed wage for no more than one month ”means that no household member is owed wage in the previous period but there is at least one household member is owed wage for no more than one month in this period. The variables, “newly unemployed ”and “newly owed pension ”, are defined in the same way. 22 arrears as instruments, we obtain the expected signs. They are jointly significant in low and the high asset groups and the p — values for the F — statistics are 0.002 and 0 respectively. Individually, three out of four predicting variables are significant for the low asset group and all of them are significant for high asset group. 1 .6 Results The estimated results of equation (1.10) for low and high asset groups are presented in Table 1.7 and 1.8 respectively. Columns (1) to (3) contain the estimation results without sample attrition correction. Columns (4) to (6) contain the estimation results with sample attrition correction. The first stage regression using predicted income change and the interaction of predicted income change and education as instrument variables for income change and the interaction of income change and demeaned education are presented in Table 1.10 in the Appendix. Comparing the OLS estimator and the IV estimators for each of the two asset group, we can see that the coefficient of income change is significantly larger in the IV results when we use wage income change to predict the household income change (1V1). It confirms our concern of measurement error in the income variable. When we use the shocks of unemployment, wage arrears and pension arrears as predictors of income change (1V2), we find that the magnitude of coefficient lies 23 in between the OLS and 1V1. It might be the case that 1V1 overestimates the consumption response to income change because it doesn’t correct for common unobservables between income change and consumption change. Sample attrition correction leads to smaller estimators of the coefficient on income change for both OLS and two IV estimations in the low asset group. In the high asset group, the coefficient of income change is bigger in IV2 after corrected for attrition. But the differences between the coefficients in the regressions with and without sample attrition correction are generally very small in magnitude. We are going to focus on the IV2 regression results with sample attrition correction in the following analysis. Neither the low asset nor the high asset group can completely smooth their con- sumption. The coefficient on the income change means how consumption change responds to income change for the household whose member has average education level 18. For example, in the low asset group (Column 6 in Table 1.8, if income change 10%, consumption will change 1.74% for the household whose member has 11 years of education . In the high asset group (Column 6 in Table 1.9), 10% change in income will lead to 0.95% change in consumption for the household with 11 years of education. Education effect on consumption smoothing is found in high asset group but not in the low asset group. In the high asset group, the coefficient on the interaction term of income change and education is -0.0386, significantly different from 0 at 10% significant level. It means that if the household has a 18 The average years of education is 11 years for the low asset group and 13 years for the high asset group. 24 university graduate 19, for example , then a 10% change in income only causes a 0.58% change in consumption. The result is puzzling because we might expect that people in the low asset group would draw on their human capital more in times of income shock but the wealth effect in the high asset group might outweigh any education effect. What we find here, however, is that education and wealth are complements and that human capital can help people to better use their wealth in smoothing consumption against income shock. Assets are significant in helping the households in the low asset group to smooth their consumption and not surprisingly, the asset effect is not significant in the high asset group. As we can see in the descriptive statistics (Table 1.2), net income per capita in the high asset group is about 32.8% higher than that in the low asset group. At the time of income shock, the households in the the high asset group do not necessarily need to sell or rent out their assets, but for the low asset group, drawing on their assets may be one of the main options to cope with the shock. For the low asset group, drawing down the assets by 10% can increase the consumption by 0.39%. The coefficient on the number of children in the initial period has a different sign in the two groups and both of them are significant. It seems that children can help, in some way, the households in the low asset group to smooth consumption. One explanation for this result may be related to means-testing schemes in child benefits 19University graduate on average has 16.03 years of education in the sample. 25 in Russia. 20 The child benefits that low income households receive may serve to help the households to smooth their consumption. For the high asset group, the presence of children in the first period doesn’t have any consumption smoothing effect. Instead, if there are more children in the first period, consumption will increase, possibly to meet the growth of the children. For households in both groups, the change in the number of senior people has a negative and significant effect on consumption change. One more senior person in the household is related to a 0.37% and 0.16% decrease in consumption for the low asset and high asset groups respectively. It may just be due to the fact that seniors do not consume as much as younger people. Alternatively, living arrangements with a senior person might be related to whether the pension payment is fulfilled. If a household’s members choose to live with seniors when they have pensions, then we can see a negative sign in the change of number of old people in the households because the households with more old people will have better means to cope with income shocks. But the causation could go other way from smoothing consumption to attracting seniors. If this is the case, then the coefficient on the change of senior people is not consistently estimated in this specification. Although we don’t focus on the endogenous living arrangement here, caution should be taken in interpreting this result. 20In 1991, the government introduced a special child support benefit to be paid to all families with children. In 1995 some regional governments decided to limit the payments of child support benefits to only the poor families. In 1997-1998, a federal law was adopted, which limited the payments to only the families with per capita income below the regional subsistence level. See Denisova, Kolenikov and Yudaeva (2000) on the child benefits policy in Russia. 26 The coefficients on the year dummies measure how consumption changes during 1996-1998 and 1998-2000 compared with the 1995-1996 period. For the households in low asset group, consumption decreased by 18.8% during 1996-1998 compared with the 1995-1996 period. For the households in high asset group, consumption decreased by 27.2% . These differences are not statistically significant. During the 1998-200 period, consumption increased by 43.7% for the low asset group and 24.4% for the high asset group, compared with 1995-1996 period. These are statistically different at 10% significance level21. This means that consumption recovered more during the 1998-2000 period for the low asset group than for the high asset group. This result is consistent with the findings that there is a de- cline in inequality during the 1998-2000 period and much of this decline is due to government transfers and pension payments (Mroz, Henderson and Popkin 2001). To check whether dropping the 1994 data will lead to different estimation results, we include the 1994 data in the regression without the interaction term of income change and years of education (since 1994 data doesn’t contain information on years of education). Instead we include three dummies to identify the four cate- gorical education groups. The results are presented in Table 1.12 and Table 1.13 in the appendix. The inverse probability weights are calculated in the same way as Section 4 but using 1994 as the first period. Almost all the previous results hold in these regression with 1994 data. The coefficient of income change in the high asset group (Column 6 Table 1.12) is 0.1451 lower than 0.1679 (Column 6 Table 21The p — value is 0.053. 27 1.8) when 1994 data is not included. The regressions in Table 1.12 don’t count for the differential consumption smoothing across households with different human capital while the coefficient of 0.1679 in Table 1.8 is the consumption response to income change for household whose members have average education level. The coefficient of income change in the low asset group (Collum 6 Table 1.11) doesn’t differ significantly from that in Column 6 of Table 1.7 when we exclude 1994 data (0.1657 vs. 0.1608). This is not surprising. Since no education effect is found in the low asset group, without including interaction term of income change and education in Table 1.11 shouldn’t change the coefficient on income change. Different regressions without education interaction term are also reported in Table 1.13 and Table 1.14. Without controlling for education effect, the coefficients of income change increase in both of the assets group. It is intriguing, especially for low asset group, where we do not find education effect on consumption smoothing. When we pool the asset group together (Table 1.15), the education effect is not significant. As we observe earlier, that the education effect exists in high asset group only, thus it might be the case that such effect is not dominant in the whole sample. The results of the regressions for the whole sample, but with income change interacting with asset group dummy variable is reported in Table 1.16. And the results for including the interaction terms for both asset group and education are included in Table 1.17. Those results yield insignificant coefficients on income change variable. Such results are likely to be caused by multicollinearity, due to 28 the interaction terms. 1 .7 Conclusions Using the Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS), we examine the differ- ences of consumption insurance between two groups of households based on their initial asset level. In the econometric model, we corrected the potential attrition bias with the inverse probability weighting method and we use the random coeffi- cient model for average treatment effect to estimate the endogenous income change and education effect. We reject the full consumption smoothing hypothesis in both wealthy and less wealthy group. We find that the education in the high asset group can increase the consumption smoothing while no education effect is detected in the low asset group. We also find that poor households may rely on their assets to smooth their consumption while assets effect is not significant in consumption equation for wealthy households. The number of children in the initial period has different impact on consumption smoothing for the poor and wealthy households. The change of policy in child support may cause this difference. The number of senior people in the households also helps to smooth consumption. And wealthy households recovered slowly from the financial shock. Several of the results needs more detailed work. For example, we found that income shocks have but small im- pact on households’ consumption. A further study of how the Russian households managed to smooth their consumption would be necessary to understand how the 29 households adjust to different shocks in the transitional economy. Multiple job holdings and living arrangement would be some topics interesting to look at. 30 Table 1.1: Household Real Income and Consumption Change Over Years and Regions Dependent Variable Income Consumption (log) per capita per capita 1 2 1 2 Year 1995 -0.314 -0.253 -0.176 -0.140 (0.019)**(3) (0.041)“ (0.019)“ (0.039)“ Year 1996 -0.476 -0.388 -0.351 -0.355 (0.025)“ (0.048)“ (0.022)“ (0.041)“r Year 1998 -0.580 -0.615 -0.718 -0.741 (0.021)“ (0.046)“r (0.021)“ (0.040)“ Year 2000 -0.388 -0.375 -0.573 -0.554 (0.021)“ (0.042)“ (0.021)“ (0.041)“ Moscow and 0.466 0.411 St. Petersburg (0.075)“ (0.078)“ Northern and 0.141 0.120 North Western (0.079)* (0.078) Volga-Vaytski and -0.079 -0.141 Volga Basin (0.051) (0.052)“ North Caucasian -0.127 0.002 (0.070)* (0.056) Ural 0.012 -0.037 (0.055) (0.058) Western Siberian 0.069 0.106 (0.069) (0.074) Eastern Siberian and 0.253 0.080 Far Eastern (0.072)“ (0.068) F-statistics for 207.39“ 49.23“ 380.98“ 111.13“ Year Dummies F -statistics for 3.42“ 2.21“ Region/ Year Dummies Number of Obs 8928 8928 8928 8928 R-squared 0.044 0.079 0.091 0.115 (1) The omitted region is Central and Central Black Earth. (2) Regressions with region dummies also include interactions between region dummies and year dummies. (3) Standard errors (robust to correlation of residuals within households and heteroscedasticity)in parentheses (4) ”indicates significance at 5% level and” 10% significant level. 31 Table 1.2: Descriptive Statistics ALL Low Assets High Assets Panel A: Household Characteristics Net Income per Capita 1181.370 889.796 1436.404 (1786.130) (1098.702) (2187.700) Total Income per Capita 1417.600 1248.402 1870.340 (1652.770) (1535.417) (2425.912) Consumption per Capita 1578.230 1141.678 1658.942 (2079.450) (1278.420) (1888.691) Total Assets 4794.190 813.749 8768.132 (9139.080) (450.440) (11623.610) Household Size 3.716 3.471 3.929 (1.516) (1.536) (1.467) Number of Seniors 0.689 0.786 0.605 (0.792) (0.776) (0.796) Number of Children 0.7981 0.673 0.906 (0.987) (1.022) (0.942) Age of Houshold Head 47.391 49.828 45.225 (14.825) (16.293) (13.011) Gender of Houshold Head 0.776 0.663 0.876 (0.417) (0.428) (0.330) Years of Education of 10.897 9.908 11.769 Household Head (3.746) (3.814) (3.558) Maximum Education 12.038 10.818 13.113 of Household Members (3.724) (3.919) (3.176) Panel B: Incidence of Unemployment, Wage Arrears and Pension Arrears Unemployment 0.120 0.111 0.127 (0.325) (0.314) (0.333) Wage Arrears 0.415 0.353 0.471 (0.493) (0.478) (0.499) Pension Arrears 0.098 0.115 0.082 (0.297) (0.319) (0.274) Panel C: Change of Unemployment,Wage Arrears and Pension Arrears Change of Unemployment 0.081 0.071 0.089 (0.272) (0.257) (0.285) Wage Arrears for 0.088 0.065 0.108 One Month or Less (0.284) (0.247) (0.311) Change of Pension Arrears 0.076 0.089 0.065 (0.265) (0.284) (0.246) Number of households 1412 673 739 (1) Net income is defined as total income not of public transfers,private transfers, unemployment benefits and incomes from sales and rental of assets. (2) Standard deviations in parentheses. 32 Table 1.3: Coefficient of Variation (CV) in Income and Consumption (per capita) All Low Assets High Assets CV for Total Income 0.562 0.549 0.575 (0287)“) (0.281) (0.292) p — value for Kruskal-Wallis test 0.037 CV for Net Incomem 0.632 0.614 0.649 (0.430) (0.444) (0.416) p — value for Kruskal-Wallis test 0.0001 CV for Consumption 0.625 0.650 0.602 (0.305) (0.324) (0.285) p — value for Kruskal-Wallis test 0.0001 Correlation of Net Income 0.4412 0.4909 0.4192 and Total Consumption Number of Households 1412 673 739 (1) Standard deviations in the parentheses. (2) Net income is defined as the total income net of public transfer, private transfer; unemployment benefits and incomes from sales and rental of assets. 33 Table 1.4: Descriptive Statistics in 1995 by Attrition Stayers Leavers p—value (1) (2) (1)-(2)- Net Income per capita 1793.554 2555.519 (38.002) (3906.432) 0.000 Consumption per capita 1264.867 1749.451 (33.343) (68.078) 0.000 Years of Education 10.899 11.212 of Household Head (0.079) (0.114) 0.024 Gender of Household 1.224 1.282 Head (0.008) (0.012) 0.0001 Moscow & St.Petersburg 0.051 0.156 (0.004) (0.009) 0.000 Household Size 3.715 3.211 (0.032) (0.038) 0.000 Age of Household Head 47.170 46.947 (0.315) (0.470) 0.693 Number of Seniors 0.690 0.537 (0.017) (0.186) 0.000 Urban 0.607 0.729 (0.010) (0.0116) 0.000 Attidude of Respond 1.231 1.280 (0.011) (0.021) 0.035 Behavior of Respond 1.186 1.211 (0.010) (0.018) 0.236 Number of Obs. 2214 1334 (1) Stayers are households which stayed all 4 rounds since 1995 survey. Leavers are households which were in 1995 survey but dropped out either in 1996,1998 or in 2000 survey. (2) Attitude=1 if household survey respondent is friendly and interested; Attitude=2 if respond is not particularly interested; Attitude=3 if respondent is impatient and worried; Attitude-=4 if respondent is hostile. (3) Behevior=1 if respondent is comfortable during the interview; Behavior=2 if respondent is occasionally nervous; Behavior=3 if respondent is nervous. (4) Standard errors in parentheses. (5)p — value is for testing the null hypothesis that the variable mean is not different across the two samples. 34 Table 1.5: Attrition Probability during 1995-2000 Dependent Variable: 1=Stay; 0=Leave (96l95) (98l96,95) (2000|98,96,95) Net Income per capita 0.034 0.016 0.026 (log) (0.022) (0.019) (0.0167) Education of -0.001 0.006 0.0067 Household Head (0.010) (0.009) (0.008) Gender of Household -0.055 -0.064 -0.056 Head (0.081) (0.069) (0.058) Age of Household 0.045 0.039 0.050 Head (0.012)“ (0.010)“ (0.086)“r Age2 of Household -00003 -00003 000% Head (0.0001)“ (0.0001)”"’r (0.0001)** Number of Seniors 0.134 0.181 0.172 (0.067)“( (0.056)“ (0.047)“ Household Size 0.087 0.075 0.076 (0.030)“ (0.026)“ (0.022)“ Moscow and -0.405 -0.367 -0.577 St. Petersburg (0.137)“ (0.127)“ (0.111)“ Northern and 0.037 0.035 0.0167 North Western (0.104) (0.092) (0.079) Volga-Vaytski and -0.266 -0.353 -0.200 Volga Basin (0.120)“( (0.105)“ (0.093)“r North Caucasian -0.101 -0.094 -0.002 (0.102) (0.091) (0.082) Ural -0.136 -0.161 -0.119 (0.118) (0.106) (0.093) Western Siberian ~0.216 -0.335 -0.318 (0.119)* (0.105)“ (0.095)“r 35 Table 1.5 (cont’d). Eastern Siberian and Far Eastern Attitude2 Attitude3 Attitude4 Behavior2 Behavior3 Number of obs (1)The omitted region is Central and Central Black Earth. 0325 (0.077)“ -0244 (0.074)“ -0.156 (0.185) -0.446 (0.440) -0.018 (0.084) 0.635 (0.239)v 2314 -0.312 (0.067)“ -0173 (0.059)“ -0249 (0.148)* -0512 (0.291)* -0014 (0.071) 0.309 (0.167)* 2129 0337 (0.060)“ -0197 (0.049)“ —0.314 (0.125)“ -0444 (0.239)* -0101 (0.056)* 0.101 (0.133) 2263 (2)Standard errors (robust to correlation of residuals within households and heteroscedasticity)in parentheses (3)**indicates significance at 5% level and"r 10% significant level. (4)Attitudc2=not particularly interested; Attitude3=impatient,worried;Attitude4= hostile. The omitted attitude category is Attitude1=friendly interested. Behavior2=occasionally nervous;Behavior3=nervous.The omitted behavior category is Behaviorlzfelt comfortable. 36 62.83 8.5 23 E 98: 30895: 23 .«o 898w was 8.853 owe some 60th 8:3 23 E efim 30855: was 9838 582:3 mo Long: 85 “on? 20880: 98 82:8 EBEEo no 838:: 85 E owfifio £8382: 20895: :38 Mo :03858 859585 mo 88» ”8538.» mosmteuoeemso 308803 AS .62: eoaaocmcwmmoag 9:85:me x. was 623 vocaofiammmam undocmcmmw .5. 885883 E Amfiozmdvoomouoaes 98 86895: 5:33 3226?: «o comes—oboe 3 8530.3 88.8 Eavfifim A: 2mm 2mm 88 88 one. 8% Bo Lo 85:2 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% 8:935 Eo%\:o%em 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% m88< ESE Eonemsom 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% 8% 852:3 mosmtmuogennv 208803 ”833213, 3:80 good mood assessed as e33 1 a 482.3 3.383 482.3 82 33> x 83. SE- was- 2325. nosed Lo mango 438.3 3.323 482.3 83. $2- 3.3. 352% season“ a0 3:20 3.883 44:33 3.833 awed- 83¢. and. satisfies: 3 355 3.333 2:3 $383 3.3 5 £52 25 $8. wood- 83. as 235. 333 822m 3.68.3 3.883 3.333 3:322: 5a 8:330 and $2. «So 4885 3.33 .8 3:20 3:80 88¢. aw;— QsoLU 88¢. 304 299% 2055 8885 wo owqeno 833.3% B89889 Emma? 4359305 882: 55 8283on mac @885 mo emceao 05 35028.?“ 64 833. 37 .383 4383 438.3 883 0.83 0.8.3 3.8 E oooo 83o oooo 8oo oooo «moo 2: 2 32m 222:8 488.3 488.3 3.883 883 4:83 4883 oesa 32 2: 5 oooo- oooo- 8o.o- mooo- 38o- 2.88. 228 8 82:2 883 883 883 :83 883 883 238.8 E 2: a 88. oooo- ooooo mooo mooo oooo 22280 co 382:2 38.3 98.3 .383 0.83 883 88.3 388. oooo- 288. 283 mooo- :oo. 28 22325: a 3820 .1883 488.3 .1383 4883 4:83 4883 228m ago. oooo- oooo- oooo- 83. ~88. Lo 23222 2: 2 3820 883 383 883 883 0.83 88.3 o2380 oooo- Koo- oooo- wooo- oooo- mooo- 8 82:2 2: 2 32220 883 883 :83 :83 883 :83 oooo Boo 8oo oooo mooo goo 22$. :28. 883 883 883 $83 88.3 883 222232 22388 0 ooooo ooooo 8oo.o- oooo oooo mooo 8:825 2:252 4:83 4883 .2883 4883 3.883 .4383 wodo ammo mooo 82o Goo mooo 3820 2:83 NE E 80 NZ 0: 80 00300800 203552 55> 20500800 sosgo< 305:5 8090 008958000 ”833.83 0808000 macaw 205$ 05 000 wEfiooEm 003082800 Kg 0305 38 0w0000 000005 20:00:00 00.0 00520.00, 0000005002 000 00 0000000 008000 E $0.000 500000 000 005 0008 00 00000.8 0mm? B0000080300000 00 09800 0000 NB .0w0000 0000000 20000000 000 000000.505 00 0000000300000 B0232: 50¢ 0000050 00805 0w03 030... «0 0w0000 0000 73 A8 ._0>0~ 0000050300002 0* 20.0 .96. 0000050wmm§m 00.0020me .11 ”0000500000 5 30030000000030: 28 020000000 02me 02.002000 .00 005200.000 00 00050: 000000 000285 AS oooo m®> 1883 008 1:83 80o- :83 oooo- 10ooo3 ooooo 1820.8 88. ooov m®> 1883 go infimodv oooo- :83 088. £883 ooooo .1883 33. oooo w®> :Awmodv oooo 1883 oooo- 883 mooo- £883 888 1883 888. oooo ooov oooo .30 00 508:2 00> 00> 00> 00000000 000>\000_w0m 1883 1883 .1883 oooo Homo Boo oooo 08> .1383 1883 1883 888- 088. oooo- 82 08> 883 883 $83 mooo- oooo- oooo- 0080 22380 00 8080 £883 £883 £883 moooo ooooo o8o.o 0.80 220250 8 no? 1083 1383 .1383 088. 888. 88. 080 220800 00 a? 3.283 5 some 39 $88.8 $88.8 $88.8 $88.8 $08.8 $Coo8 :25: E 2: Eoo oooo Boo Eoo oooo too a mum 223:0: $88.8 $88.8 $88.8 $28.8 £858 $338 :25 :2 a oodo- ado- who- So- wooo- So- acaom o: 5:52 $38.8 $388 $0058 $83.8 $38.8 $88.8 82$ :3 a oooo- oooo- oooo- oooo- :ooo- Hooo- 5:230 o: 5:52 33.8 63.8 $3.8 $3.8 $3.8 $3.8 mam Boo- Hooo goo- oooo- Soo Soo- 22880 a @0830 $28.8 $68.8 $88.8 $Aooo8 $38.8 Loooov 325m 0: oooo- oooo- oooo- 20o- go- Homo- 35:2 5 owqfio 88.8 888 3.88 88.8 88.8 38.8 5:230 o: :oo- 83. Nooo- Eoo- wooo- goo- 28:2 8 083:0 $888 38.8 $288 88.8 Aoooov $28.8 o:o.o- oooo- goo- oooo- mooo- oooo- 332 :33 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 38.8 388 38:52 228:3: o: oooo- oooo- :ooo- Hooo- soo- soo- 808:3: 8:552 :38 :58 $8.8 $8.8 88.8 8.88 83:32.: 8:852 oooo- zoo- Hooo- oooo- :oo- oooo- 8:858 x Magoo 2:85 $508 $658 $0.88 $§o8 $38.8 $888 $3 oooo Hooo ooao homo oooo 09:20 8:85 NE E 20 :2 :0 £0 005000000 00§50< 53> 005000000 005538 00055, 098:0 003083000 ”0303.3/ 0000:0000 0:000 00mm< 304 05 000 wEfiooEm 005955000 no: 05:9 40 0&0000 0000000 3000000: 000 00300000, 0000000005 00: 00 00.00000 020000 00 0m0.0:0 500000 000 0003 00000 00 0000000 0003 5000008300000 00 0w0000 0000 Na .0w0000 0000000 2000000: 000 00000000000 00 0000000000000 1003305 00000 0000300 0000000 0w03 0300 .00 0&0000 0000 Ha A3 000,00 0000050900053 0 000 000,00 00000£0w_0§m 0000E0m00 030 ”00000000000 5 33006000000230: 000 03000000: 00303 00003000 00 000300000 00 0005000 000000 0000000m AS ooom 0% $38.8 mono ihmwodv mooo- 38.8 33o- $0ooo8 moooo 3oo.8 Boo- omoo 0% $38.8 mono 00890.8 33. 3.8.8 goo- $:ooo.8 moooo «820.8 :oo- oooo 00> $38.8 :02 $3088 o:m.o- 38.8 Boo- :ooo.8 0ooo.o 3oo.8 zoo- oooo 00> $388 $2 $388 33. 38.8 oooo- $:ooo.8 moooo 38.8 Boo- oooo 00> $38.8 goo 38.8 :Eo- 32.8 Boo- :ooo8 Hoooo 388 go. omom 30 0: 088:2 00> 000000000 000>\000w0m $38.8 goo oooo 08> $338 08o- 002 08> 38.8 080 mooo- 0:903:00 0: 02080 $3808 080 moooo 2:60:00 0: 0000.. $388 080 Boo- 20:00:00 0: 00¢. 30:88 0.0 03:0 41 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 08.50 :8 8: 08.: 08.: 3:: 08:. :83- 08.8 8 :80 2:88:00 38.8 38.8 33.8 33.8 38.8 38.8 88:0 E :0 :83- 08:- 08.8 08.: 08.: 08.3- 808:0 0: 088:2 $38.8 $38.8 $388 38.8 $38.8 38.8 08.80 :8 :0 38.: 38.: 88.: 80.: 00.: 03.: 8.8080 0: 088:2 38.8 $38.8 $38.8 $32.8 $38.8 $388 800 08:- 03:- 03:- 0.3:- 03:- 03.8 8:88:00 8 00880 $38.8 $38.8 $38.8 $38.8 $388 $3.38 808:0 0: 303- 03:- 000.3. 3.3- 02.3- 80.8 888:2 8 000880 33.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 338 8:880 0: 08.8 083. 08:- :83- 38:- 03:- 808:2 8 @0880 35.8 35.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 388 2:3 08.: :0: 3:3 3:: ms: 882 08:8 388 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 888:2 8:88:00 0: 8:3- 08:- 0:83- 38:- 88.8 88.: 8:88:00 8:808: $38.8 $38.8 $38.8 3.8.8 $38.8 $38.8 8:08:00 8:80:82 32.8 08.8 20:- :33- 8.0:- 08.3- 888800 x 00:20 .888 $08.8 $33.8 $38.8 $38.8 $38.8 $38.8 0.2.: :00 08.0 02.: 80.: 003.0 00:20 088:: «>0 :0 0.00 «>0 :0 0.00 005000000 005000300. 55> GOSUWEOO goswpua< uSOSfiB 0&0000 00500000000 0EE00> 000000000 00000 000.00. 00me 0% 00m wEfiooEm 0059000000 3.0 03:8 42 0w0000 0000000 20000000: 00.0 00300000, 00000000000 00: 00 0000000 0000000 00 00000000 0030000 000 005 00000 00 0000000 0w03 .000000000000000 00 0900000 800 NE .0w00:0 0000000 000000000: 000 00000000000 00 0000000000000 0000003000 00000 0000030 0000000 0w03 00000 .00 0900000 0000 02 A3 .00>0_ 000005030003 00 000 000000 00000000300000: 000000030 0&0 0000000000000 00 30050000000030; 000 03000000: 000:3 30000000 00 0030000000 00 00050-5 000000 0000005 3v 0000 00> $300.8 000.0 $00008 0000- 300.8 0000- 00000.8 0000.0 $300.8 000.0- 0000 0% $300.8 000.0 $3008 0000- 300.8 000.0- $000008 00000 $3008 000.0- 0000 00> $300.8 000.0 $200.8 000.0- 300.8 000.0- $000008 0000.0 $300.8 000.0- 0000 00> $3008 0000 $300.8 000.0- 300.8 000.0- $000008 0000.0 300.8 000.0- 0000 w®> «#Gvodv 0000 $3008 0000- 300.8 000.0 0000.8 0000.0 $300.8 000.0- 0000 00> $300.8 0000 $3008 0000. 0000.8 000.0- $000008 0000.0 1320.8 000.0- 000 00 0000000 Z 000000005 000>\000w0m ooom 000> wag 000> 0003 20000000: .00 000000 0.80 200000000: 00 N0W0. 000m 0000000003 00 0m< 00.880 0.0 030-0 43 BIBLIOGRAPHY Altonji, J. G., F. Hayashi, and L. J. Kotlikoff (1992), “Is the Extended Family Altruistically Linked? Direct Tests Using Micro Data,” The American Economic Review Vol. 82, No. 5: 1177-1198. Arrow, K. (1964), “The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bear- ing, ”Review of Economic Studies 31: 91-96. Cochrane, J. H. (1991), “A Simple Test of Consumption Insurance,” The Journal of Political Economy Vol. 99, Issue 5: 957-976. Deaton, A. (1997), The Analysis of Household Surveys Baltimore: The Johns Hop- kins University Press. Deaton, A. (1992), Understanding Consumption Oxford, Clarendon Press. Dynarski, S., and J. Gruber (1997), “Can Families Smooth Variable Earnings?, ”Booking Papers on Economic Activity Vol. 1997, Issue 1: 299-284. Glewwe, P., and G. Hall (1998), “Are Some Groups More Vulnerable to Macroeco- nomic Shocks Than Others? Hypothesis Tests Based on Panel Data from Peru,” Journal of Development Economics Vol. 56: 181-206. Grimard, F. (1997),“Household Consumption Smoothing through Ethnic Ties: Ev- idence from Cote D’Ivoire,” Journal of Development Economics v53, n2, 391-422. Jalan, J ., and M. Ravallion ( 1999), “Are the Poor Less Well Insured? Evidence on Vulnerability to Income Risk in Rural China,” Journal of Development Economics Vol.58: 61—81. Jensen, R., and K. Richter (2002), “Social Security, Income Volatility and Health: Evidence from The Russian Pension Crisis,” Working Paper. Lokshin, M., and M. Ravallion (2000), “Welfare Impacts of the 1998 Financial Cri- sis in Russia and the Response of the Public Safety Net,” Economics of Transition. Vol. 8(2), 269-295. 44 Mace, B. J.(1991), “Full Insurance in the Presence of Aggregate Uncertainty,” Journal of Political Economy v99, n5: 928-56 McCarthy, J. (1995), “Imperfect Insurance and Differing Propensities to Consume Across Households,” Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 36: 301-327. Michael, R. (1973), “Education in Nonmarket Production,” The Journal of Political Economics Vol.81, Issue 2, Part 1: 306-327. Morduch, J. (1995), “Income Smoothing and Consumption Smoothing,” Journal of Economic Perspective Vol. 9, Number 3: 103-114. Mroz. T. and B. Popkin (1995),“Poverty and the Economic Transition in the Russian Federation,”. Economic Development and Cultural Change Vol. 44: 1-31. Mroz, T., D.Mancini, and B. Popkin (1999), “Monitoring Economic Conditions in Russian Federation: The Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey 1992-1998,” Report submitted to the US. Agency for International Development. Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, North Carolina. Mroz, T., L. Henderson, and B. Popkin (2001), “Monitoring Economic Condi- tions in Russian Federation: The Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey 1992- 2000,” Report submitted to the US. Agency for International Development. Car- olina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, North Car- olina. Paxson, C. (1992), “Using Weather Variability to Estimate the Response of Savings to 'Dansitory Income in Thailand,”American Economic Review 82 no. 1: 15-33. Rosenzweig, M. R. (1988), “Risk, Implicit Contracts and the Family in Rural Areas of Low-Income Countries,” The Economic Journal Issue 393: 1148-1170. Schultz, T. W. (1975), “The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequilibria, ” Jour- nal of Economic Literature, Vol 13, Issue 3: 827-846. Stillman, S. (2001), “The Response of Consumption in Russian Households to Economic Shocks ”Rand Working Paper. 45 Strauss, J., and D. Thomas (1995), “Human Resources: Empirical Modeling of Household and Family Decisions,” Handbook of Development Economics Vol. III A Elsevier Science B.V. Townsend, R. M. (1994), “Risk and Insurance in Village India, ”Econometrica Vol. 62, No. 3: 539-591. Townsend, R. M. (1995), “Consumption Insurance: An Evaluation of Risk-Bearing Systems in Low-Income Economies, ”Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol. 9, No. 3: 83-102. Welch, F. (1970), “Education in Production, ”The Journal of Political Economy Vol. 78, Issue 1: 35-39. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002a), “Inverse Probability Weighted M—Estimation for Sam- ple Selection, Attrition and Stratification,” Portuguese Economic Journal 1:117- 139. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002b), “Further Results on Instrumental Variables Estimation of Average 'IYeatment Effects In The Correlated Random Coefficient Model,” mimeo, Department of Economics, Michigan State University. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002c), “Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data ”MIT press: Cambridge, MA. 46 APPENDIX Table 1.10: First Stage Regression Dependent Variable: Income Change Income Change x Demeaned Maximum Education IV1 IV2 IV1 IV2 Panel A: Whole Sample Predicted Income Change 1 1.000 (0.088)“ Predicted Income Change 2 1.000 (0.138)“ Control Variables: Household Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Household Total Assets Yes Yes Yes Yes Region/ Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Number of Obs 4236 4236 4236 4236 Panel B: Low Asset Group Predicted Income Change 1 0.327 -11.914 (0.293) (1.559)“ Predicted Income Change 1 0.058 1.027 X Maximum Education (0.024)“r (0.121)“ Predicted Income Change 2 0.539 -8.306 (0.281)* (1.192)“ Predicted Income Change 2 0.043 0.766 x Maximum Education (0.038) (0.121)“ Control Variables: Household Characteristics Yes Yes Yes Yes Household Total Assets Yes Yes Yes Yes Region / Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Number of Obs 2020 2020 2020 2020 47 Table 1.10 (cont’d). Panel C: High Asset Group Predicted Income Change 1 Predicted Income Change 1 x Maximum Education Predicted Income Change 2 Predicted Income Change 2 x Maximum Education Control Variables: Household Characteristics Household Total Assets Region/ Year Dummy Number of Obs 1.752 (0.358)“ -0053 (0.025)“ Yes Yes Yes 2216 1.165 (0.277)“ -0.014 (0.023) Yes Yes Yes 2216 -3.054 (2.453) 0.313 (0195) Yes Yes Yes 2216 -5.778 (0.962)“ 0.553 (0.090)“ Yes Yes Yes 2216 (1) Predicted Income Change 1 is fitted value of income change using change of wage earnings obtained from individual survey as predictor. Predicted income change 2 is fitted value of income change using unemployment shock, wage arrears shock and pension shock as predictors. (2) Standard errors (robust to correlation of residuals within households and heteroscedasticity) in parentheses *‘k significant 5% significance level and * significant 10%significance level. (3) Household characteristics variables: years of maximum education of the household members; change in the number of children; seniors and household size; the number of children, seniors and household size in the first period; age, age squared and gender of the household head in the first period. 48 .1333 3.333 $333 :33 :33 333 85a E 5 33- 33- 33- N33- 333- 333. eoeom 3 2882 $333 .1333 1.333 83.3 $3.3 2.3.3 333 E a 33- :33- 333- :33- 333- 333- 8330 3 285:2 $3.3 33.3 83.3 83.3 33.3 :33 33 33.3.. 333 333- 33.3- 233. 333- 22383 a @330 1.83.3 £333 #333 1.223 162.3 1823 333 333- 33.3- 333- 333- 33- 32- 3 338:2 5 @325 63.3 33.3 33.3 63.3 33.3 63.3 5330 3 333- 333- 333- 333- N33- 333- 2352 a .336 83.3 $3.3 33.3 33.3 83.3 33.3 5330 .3. a 33.3 333 333 33 33 :33 853:3 8:852 33.3 33.3 83.3 33.3 33.3 93.3 E330 33 a 333 33.3 333 333- 333- 53- 85323.. 5:852 33.3 $3.3 $3.3 33.3 :33 33.3 3.5330 33 a :33- 333- 333- 33.3. 333- 33.3- 3335 asses: 33.3 33.3 .333 .333 :33 .833 333- :33- 33- 333- 333- 33.3- eon-.3. 33. .333 #333 £333 1.333 13:33 .1833 333 33 333 33 :33 333 3:30 3885 NE E So 3: E 30 33 3 39:5, QED vm 55> own-EU 2053:5380 33> .anQ 3:80 uomm< 304 [13ng «0mm: 305:5 m> 33>? 3:33“ :ommmoawom ”SA 2nt 49 0:530 «0:0 56:03:: 3 ~0>0~ £59m 400500 3:05:09, mm _0>0_ EBB .Am0wgw oHHV . :0330300 53::0000 130:0»: mm _0>0_ ::000m 383% 3 VV .8333? 3:30:88 3:0:0w 30:0: 3 _0>0_ :0530200 3:583 $53233 3:053:05 05 mm 350:3 :0_m:0: E 0w§fio ”5:9: 0:0 :35 0:05 0: 0.80:3 0mm? 65:32:53: .«0 0w:-m;0 80: NE 038:0 0:805 20:03.0: :8 3:063:05 00 0305050030 33:03:05 80b 8:850 0:505 0mm? :30... mo 0w:0;0 000: CC A8 .~0>0_ 00::0m3w6332 3:05:30 3 :90 ER: 00:85:30R0m. 3:005:30 I 0000558: 5 3205038002030: 98 3:050:03 :23? £03300: “0 :0530300 0... 30:20.; 20:0 :8::3m 2V 3333 8> $:3.3 333 «.waodv 3:3- 833 333- $:33.3 3333 Lmoodv 333- $633 333 3333 33> $333 333 33.3 333- C33 333- $:333.3 3333 $833 :33- $:3.3 333 3333 33> $833 333 $833.33 333- $333 333- $:333.3 3333 *Amoodv 333- $333 333 3333 33> $:3.3 333 $83.33 :33- $333 333. 63.3 :33- :333 333 333.3 333- 83.3 333 3333 00> $333 333 $833 333- $333 33. 33.3 333 :3333 3333 33.3 333- 33.3 333 3333 m®> $333 333 $:3.3 333- 633 3:3- 333 :33- :3333 3333 333.3 333- :33 333 30 “0 30:8: Z 00:88:: 30>\:0_w0m ooom 30> wag 50> 82 330% 30m 20:03:02 “0 30:50 30m 20:03:03 “0 ~0w< @303 20:03:03 30 0m< vow-Sm 33H 05 5 03m 20:03:0m .2583 2.: 233- 50 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 38.8 38.8 825 E 2: 8o.o- 83. ~88. zoo- zoo- Boo- a 38 223.2% $8.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 €88 $8.8 Bram E 5 oooo oooo 8o.o- o8.o o8.o oooo 158% 8 38:2 1288 188.8 188.8 188.8 188.8 188.8 Beam 2 E 888 oooo Goo wooo goo 88o 9:220 8 58:52 1888 188.8 188.8 1688 1:88 £288 38 goo- goo- goo- go- Eoo- Eoo- 2238: a 855 188.8 188.8 188.8 18988 18898 13888 958% o0 838. oooo- «So- oodo- 2:8. 83. 38:2 a @8526 $88 88.8 88.8 :88 88.8 38.8 5:230 o0 888. M88. mooo- M88. 88. 988. 38:2 5 8:30 38.8 $8.8 $8.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 boosoo £8 a oooo- oooo- 8o.o «.88 ovoo goo 838:5 8:852 88.8 :88 38.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 8828 Ho 8 goo- moo- 8o.o- «.88 «88 $88 oossoom 8:852 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 $8.8 88.8 30380 EN a 888. go. goo- oooo oooo goo 5:828 8:852 :88 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 Eoo Eoo o8.o oooo oooo 8o.o 33$. 38 188.8 188.8 188.8 1888 1:88 188.8 8:8 83 oooo oodo oEo wooo 8526 0885 82 So So NZ go So 83 8 82:3 33 8 55> @95on sowoaasmcoo ”.83 .onQ @280 ommm< :wi 1885 $2 820355 m> 55> mfizmom commmmowom ”NH; 2an 51 .264: 98 3853:: mm ~92 :35.“ 48:8 3:058? E 732 BEE A8688 SUV . 583:3 DEESmm 855w 8 6%: 388m .Awowfiw 3 VV 558:8 5:503 885% 323 mm ER: 538:? ambamv 838:8, «5:5,:me 2: mm 989:: 588: E mwfifio ”5:2: 28 :8: v.88 0: 38b: emu? 5553382: We vwfifio mom: Na 6885 2:85 20585: :8 “=88:me ma 38::2826 833365 Eob 8:830 2:85 am?» 138 go wwfifio 8m: H>~ A3 :96: 8585:8989 €85:me 1 :5 ~86: 8:8cfiwmmo8m “:85:me fr $8558: 5 Amfiofimdeomohmumn v5 mEonmmso: :3me flag—Ema: mo :052280 3 38508 $0th @8285 AC S8 88 88 S8 98 28 80 8 38oz m®> m®> m®> wm> mm.» m®> @285va Hmm>\flomw.®m 1:88 1888 188.8 168.8 1:88 1:88 :88 o8.o v88 83 :88 88o oooo 5% 188.8 188.8 1:88 1:88 1:88 1:88 88o- mono- 888- 82- oooo- :88. 82 50> 88.8 88.8 :88 ~88- oooo- «88 o8: 5% :88 :88 :88 :88 88.8 :88 :8: 88.8 83 8.8 83 8o.o 83. 2288: 8 “880 188.8 188.8 188.8 88.8 88.8 888 So: 888 8oo.o 888 888 8oo.o 888 2238: 8 031 188.8 188.8 188.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 88: Eoo- Boo- o8.o- ooo.o- oooo- Boo- 22:80: 8 a? 8.888 2.: 2%? 52 188.8 188.8 1:88 1:88 1888 1:88 :28: 8: :88 888 888 888 888 8.88 2: a 88 88888: 1:88 1:88 1:88 1:88 1:88 1:88 :28: 8: 2: 5 888- 888- 888- 888- 88- 888- 8888 8 8:882 1:88 1:88 138.8 88.8 :88 1:88 8:8: 8: 2: a 888- 888- 8o.o- 888- 888- 888- 8880 8 8:882 :88 88.8 88.8 :88 88.8 88.8 888- 88. :88- 888- 888- 888. 88 88888: a 8880 188.8 1:28 1:88 1:888 1888 182.8 8888 888- 888. 888- 888- 888- 888- 8 8:882 2: a 88:0 88.8 88.8 :88 :88 :88 :88 888:0 888- 888- 888- 88. 888- 888- 8 8882 2: 8 88:0 1:88 :88 1:88 :88 88.8 :88 :88- 88- 888- 888- 888- 88. :88 88:- :88 $8.8 :88 888.8 :88 :88 888882 88888: oo 88 888 88 888 88 888 8:88: 888882 1:28 1888 1:88 1:28 1888 1:88 8:8 888 888 88 :88 888 88:0 8885 82 :2 8:0 82 E So 8:058:00 :o§:S< 5:5 5:38:00 BUSES-8: 305:5 mwSEO 8858558580 ”83883 8:288:95 CEBU-8:85 983833. gofimgv 95:0 8088:. 304 :8 wEEooEm 85:83:00 ”24 @388 53 8888 m®> 18888 888.8 18888 888.8- «vaodv 8888- 1888.8 8888.8 1888 888.8- 8888 w®> 18888 888 1:88.88 8888- 18888 88.8- 1888.8 8888.8 1:88 888.8- .9588 8:8 38-83:; mm 3?: 530m .3083. Enos-80> mm .832 8.838 .Awmfiflw SUV . 85:89:88. E88888 88.85% £ ER: 853% A883» 3 VV coma-8:888 88.88.8888 355% 3285 2. ~92 88382888 888593 @5833 30538.85 23 md 8.88:8 :06ch E mwsdgo ”5:9: 28 58:8 808 o: 8888 .8me 385588383: .80 $530 mom: Na .8955 2:85 83:88:08 5.8 8888:me m8 Padanoflmmsc 88:88:85 508 885830 2:85 “Wm-83 833 we mmfifio 8m: :3 A8 .832 won-8088:3882 8:865:me .8 8:8 _m>w_ mogocammfim 8:85:me f8 mwmmficoamm E Qflofimaggggg 8:8 £83535: 5585 E83868 mo .8883.on 08 $8505 8.88.8 8.8855 CV 8888 88> 18888 888.8 iAvadV 8888- 1:888 8888- 1888.8 8888.8 1888 8888. 8888 88> 18888 888.8 1888 88.8- 8888 88.8- 1888.8 8888.8 :Afifiodv 888.8- .880 mo 888: Z 828859 88o>\50_wom ooom “88> wag 58> 883-“ 8680850: mo .8850 888: 83888:on mo mmw< 88mm anwmsom mo ow< 8,888 8: 888,8 54 $8.8 $8.8 $8.3 coooo 38.8 33.8 35 E oooo oooo oooo Hooo- Hooo- oooo- 2: a 3% Eofimoom $8.8 $8.8 88.8 63.8 smog 38.8 cocoa o2 2: 5 oooo- Hooo- oooo- mooo- oooo- oooo- 228m o0 5952 Looooo Looooo Looooo $8.8 Looooo Loooov 35 E 2: 5 oooo oooo ovoo oooo oooo ovoo 5620 E soaoz 88.8 Loooov Loooov Looooo flooov Looooo «moo- Boo- oooo- goo- Soo- oooo- mam Eoogoom a omoooo r838 Ltooo :Eoov tfloooov $38.3 .9383 228m $8- 83. ES. $3. $3. oodo- o0 352 2: a mango $8.3 Cooov :oooo sooov Cooov Cooov 8.220 Boo- Soo- Hooo- :oo- :oo- oooo- oo soaoz 2: a voodoo aoooo Afioov $8.8 $5.8 Loooov Afiooo Soo Soo oooo oooo oooo oooo 3&2 Eco $8.8 $8.8 cooov $8.3 $8.8 38.3 28%: ooooomoom oo Hooo- Hooo- ooooo- ooooo- ooooo- ooooo- :osoosom 8:852 $38.3 rcoooo $88.8 $35.8 :Coooo 135.3 go oooo Soo moao oofio oooo mango 2:85 NE 5 £0 NE So So 2050250 coSEo< 55> :oSomtoO ”8353‘ 393:5 wwSfiO cosqfigaoo ”wamEdN/ unowcoaoa Acosowoofi: ~568st osofigc anew oomm< swam .5“ wEfiooEm 5:385:00 ”EA 2nt 55 .9690 0:0 36003:: mm _0>0~ 5.59m 30:00 1503009, $ _0>0_ EBB .Ammvflw 3H8 . 00:00:00 0000:0000 1.200% E ER: 008% $0an 3 VV 00300300 38000000 350% 3303 mm 62: 00300300 uBEAS mflnflg 0:08:59: 05 00 802.8 020000 E 030:0 50:08 000 :2: 0008 0: 9800.3 0w?» #:0050383: .80 030:0 89 NB .mwzafi 08005 20:09.0; 00w 3083505 no 0035530000 2033?: Bob 000850 08005 0mg, :38 80 098:0 wow: 35 Amy 40%: 00:00aEwmmvooH 0:005:me « 0:.» ER: mocaocawmwfixon 0:03:36 I 83500an 5 30803000080080: 0:0 0205000: 555 015208 “0 003200000 00 00000.8 80:0 vowvnwum A3 SE SE oao Boo Boo oao .30 oo soaoz m®> mm> mm.» m®> mo> m®> momaafla udm>\fimomwmwm $33.8 $33.8 $338 $338 $33.8 $33.8 20o oao oooo :oo oao mooo oooo 5% % $28.8 $38.8 $28.8 $38.8 $33.8 $23.8 zoo- Homo- mono- go. go. oooo- oooo 3% 38.8 33.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 38.8 oooo- mooo- oooo- oooo- oooo- zoo- 3% 220200 3 350 £888 L888 L888 $:ooo.8 $:ooo.8 $:ooo.8 ooooo ooooo ooooo ooooo ooooo ooooo 2% 223.8: oo $3. $38.8 $38.8 $388 38.8 $38.8 $38.8 Boo- Boo- Boo- zoo- zoo- 38o- Ham 2302550 e? .3088 o: 2330. Table 1.15: Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group (With Education Interaction; With Attrition Correction) Dependent Variables: Consumption Change OLS IV1 IV2 Income Change 0.062 0.257 0.169 (0.020)“ (0.044)“r (0.058)“r Income Changex Demeaned -0.007 -0.031 -0.024 Maximum Education (0.005) (0.014)“ (0.021) Maximum Education -0.0002 -0.0003 -0.0004 Of Household Members (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Total Assets -0.003 -0.001 -0.002 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) Change in the Number of -0.035 -0.035 -0.036 Children (0.042) (0.045) (0.043) Change in the Number of -0.239 -0.214 -0.229 Seniors (0.057)“ (0.059)W (0.059)“ Change in Household Size —0.044 -0.034 -0.037 (0.027)* (0.027) (0.027) Number of Children -0.0002 -0.004 -0.003 In the lst Period (0.019) (0.020) (0.019) Number of Seniors —0.062 -0.059 -0.062 In the lst Period (0.030)“ (0.030)* (0.031)“ Household Size in the 0.025 0.026 0.026 lst Period (0.015)* (0.015)* (0.015)* Age of Household Head -0.015 -0.016 -0.016 (0.006)“ (0.006)“ (0.006)“ Age2 of Household Head 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 (0.0001)Hr (0.0001)** (0.0001)** Gender of Household Head -0.028 -0.028 -0.029 (0.026) (0.027) (0.027) Year 1998 -0.300 -0.229 -0.261 (0.048)“ (0.050)“ (0.051)“ Year 2000 0.302 0.271 0.285 (0.036)“ (0.039)“ (0.038)” Regioin/Year Dummies Yes 4395 Yes Number of Obs. 4236 4236 4236 See notes in Table 1.14 57 Table 1.16: Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group (With Asset Inter- action; With Attrition Correction) Dependent Variables: Consumption Change OLS IV1 IV2 Income Change 0.006 0.511 0.342 (0.075) (0.170)“ (0.262) Income Changex Asset Group 0.006 -0.036 -0.025 (0.009) (0.020)* (0.033) Maximum Education 0.0001 -0.0001 -0.0002 Of Household Members (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Total Assets -0.003 -0.0013 -0.001 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) Change in the Number of -0.032 -0.034 -0.035 Children (0.042) (0.045) (0.043) Change in the Number of —0.237 -0.211 -0.226 Seniors (0.057)“ (0.059)“ (0.059)“ Change in Household Size -0.045 -0.038 -0.040 (0.027)* (0.027) (0.027) Number of Children -0.005 -0.005 -0.004 In the lst Period (0.019) (0.020) (0.020) Number of Seniors -0.061 —0.058 -0.061 In the lst Period (0.030)“ (0.030)* (0.030)“r Household Size in the 0.025 0.025 0.025 lst Period (0.015)* (0.015)* (0.015)* Age of Household Head -0.015 -0.016 -0.016 (0.006)“ (0.006)“ (0.006)” Age2 of Household Head 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 (00001)“r (0.0001)** (00001)“ Gender of Household Head -0.026 -0.025 -0.027 (0.026) (0.027) (0.027) Year 1998 -0.302 -0.231 -0.263 (0.048)“ (0.051)“ (0.052)“ Year 2000 0.303 0.270 0.285 (0.036)“ (0.039)W (0.038)“ Regioin / Year Dummies Yes Yes Yes Number of Obs. 4236 4236 4236 See notes in Table 1.14 58 Table 1.17: Correction) Consumption Smoothing for Pooled Asset Group(With Educa- tion/ Assets Interaction; With Attrition Dependent Variables: Consumption Change OLS IV1 IV2 Income Change -0.097 0.367 0.239 (0.097) (0.176)Mr (0.272) Income Change x Asset Group 0.064 0.022 —0.007 (0.060) (0.116) (0.205) Income Changex Demeaned 0.015 -0.008 -0.022 Maximum Education (0.032) (0.062) (0.124) Income Changex Asset Group -0.003 —0.003 —0.0002 x Demeaned Maximum Education (0.004) (0.008) (0.015) Maximum Education -0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0004 Of Household Members (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Total Assets -0.003 -0.0005 -0.002 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) Change in the Number of -0.033 -0.039 -0.038 Children (0.042) (0.045) (0.044) Change in the Number of -0.234 -0.215 -0.231 Seniors (0.058)“ (0.059)“ (0.060)“r Change in Household Size -0.045 -0.035 -0.037 (0.027)* (0.027) (0.027) Number of Children 0.001 -0.005 -0.003 In the lst Period (0.019) (0.020) (0.020) Number of Seniors -0.061 -0.060 -0.063 In the 1st Period (0.030)“ (0.030)“ (0.031)“r Household Size in the 0.025 0.026 0.026 lst Period (0.015)* (0.015)* (0.015)* Age of Household Head -0.015 -0.017 -0.016 (0.006)“ (0.006)“r (0.006)“ Age2 of Household Head 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 (00001)“r (0.0001)** (0.0001)** Gender of Household Head -0.026 -0.029 -0.030 (0.026) (0.027) (0.027) Year 1998 —0.299 -0.228 -0.262 (0.048)“ (0.050)“ (0.051)“ Year 2000 0.302 0.271 0.285 (0.036)“ (0.039)“ (0.038)W F —test of Interaction Terms 3.02 2.00 0.71 p — value of F statistics 0.0286 0.112 0.548 Regioin/Year Dummies Yes Yes Yes Number of Obs. 4236 4236 4236 See notes in Table 1.14 59 Chapter 2 Multiple Job Holdings As a Way to Smooth Consumption: Labor Response to Wage Arrears Among Russian Couples 2.1 Introduction During ten years of economic and social transition, Russia has witnessed a weak correlation between employment change and output change: the declines in total employment were substantially below the steep declines in GDP 1. Instead of mass layoffs, wage arrears, unpaid administrative leave and short-time work were common practices adopted by the employers as adjustment mechanisms. Among these practices, wage arrears were the dominant form of labor market adjustment and the main source of insecurity for Russian workers (Lehmann, Wadsworth and 1Between 1990 and 1998, GDP fell by about 45%, while aggregate employment declined by about 16%. OECD (2001) 60 Acquisti (1999)). At the end of 1998, nominal wage arrears reached 77 billion roubles, which was equivalent of 200 percent of the monthly wage bill. After three years of recovery from the 1998 financial crisis, by the end of 2001, the stock of wage arrears was reduced to 29.9 billion roubles but was still higher than the level of 17.5 billion roubles in 1995.2 Wage nonpayment was also pervasive in terms of the percentage of working people affected: about 64% of working age men and women were owed wages in 1998 and this number was still over 25% in 2001(Mroz, Osmolovskii and Popkin, 2002). Various studies have shown that workers respond actively in one way or another to wage arrears. For example, using nationally representative household survey data together with matched firm-individual data, Earle and Sabirianova (2002) found that wage arrears have a positive impact on workers’ quits in the regions where wage arrears level are less than average. Lehmann, Wadsworth and Acquisti (1999) also found that wage arrears positively affect the incidence of job-to-job movement and such effect is strengthened by the viability of the outside labor market. Foley(1997) looked at the individual pattern of transitions between labor market states from 1992 to 1996 in a pooled cross section data set and found that wage arrears had no effect on propensity to switch jobs; however, wage arrears increased the probability of taking on additional work (Foley 1997b). Desai and Idson (2001) detected worker-initiated turnover among workers subjected to wage nonpayment. Moreover, they found that although wage arrears had no effect on 2Russian Economic T‘rends,June 1999,vol.8, no.4 ; December 2002, vol 11, no.4 61 the tendency of workers to hold more than one formal job, wage arrears did have distinct labor supply effects with respect to less formal supplemental work. Given that labor markets are flexible, any labor response, particularly an increase in household labor supply in secondary jobs, might mitigate the negative impact of wage arrears in the primary job on household consumption. It has been well known that labor supply is an alternative to dissaving, asset decumulation, or increasing debt in the attempts of households to maintain consumption in the face of declining income (Mincer 1962). Various studies have focused on the labor market responses, such as hours worked, self-employment and household labor supply to economic shocks 3. Empirical evidence also shows that shift of labor from farm to off-farm employment can explain the observed lack of correlation between consumption and idiosyncratic crop shocks in rural India (Kochar 1999). To test the hypothesis that in Russian economy the labor response helps to mitigate the impact of wage arrears on household consumption, we focus on multiple job holdings by household members. 4 Applying a test proposed by earlier research (Kochar 1999), our reduced-form regression of consumption on wage arrears reveals no significant effect of wage arrears in the primary job on household consumption. 5 3Smith, Thomas, Frankenberg, Beegle, and Teruel (2002) on Indonesia; McKenzie (2003a) on Mexico and Mckenzie (2003b)on Argentina. 4The impact of wage arrears on total working hours is ambiguous because it might reflect job changes. Furthermore, changing primary jobs need not reflect the desire of the household to smooth their consumption because with well-functioned labor market, job-specific shocks would result in a shift to new jobs, even if households have access to insurance market (Kochar 1999). 5This result is consistent with the result in our previous findings that the consumption of Russian households was relatively well protected from shocks such as wage arrears, pension arrears and unemployment. 62 Conditional on multiple job holdings, however, wage arrears have a negative effect on consumption. This result confirms that the ability to smooth consumption in times of wage arrears reflects, in some part, multiple job holdings of the male and female household heads. The experience of wage arrears by one individual can trigger the change of worker’s labor allocation from one job to another job or from single job holding to multiple job holding, as documented in the previous literature. At the same time, it may also affect the consumption-leisure decision within his / her household and change the labor supply of other household members. Previous theoretical analysis high- lights the implications of income shocks on spousal labor supply in a household life-cycle model in which individual’s labor supply increases when exogenous shocks experienced by their spouse causes a transitory reduction in their household in- come.6 In the case of wage arrears, if individual worker responds to their own wage arrears by increasing labor supply, then the cross effect of wage nonpayment on spouse labor supply might be subdued. In our estimation of household labor supply responses to wage arrears shocks, we analyze how individual labor supply responds to wage arrears experienced by the spouse. Unlike previous studies of “the added worker effect ”, which focus on the wife’s labor supply response to the husband’s labor market shock, we examine the labor supply response of both wife and husband to the wage nonpayment experienced by their spouse. It is necessary 6The effect of a husband’s job loss on the labor supply of his wife is known as the “added worker ”effect (Mincer 1962; Heckman and MaCurdy 1980; Lundberg 1985; Stephens 2001; ect.) 63 in the context of the Russian labor market to include both women and men in the analysis because the labor force participation rate of women is comparable to that of men.7 In our estimation of multiple job holdings as well as job-to-job movement, we apply the “Chamberlain ”approach to a dynamic probit model. This model explicitly allows individual fixed effects to be correlated with time varying variables including the incidence of wage nonpayment. It is especially useful because the unobserved time-invariant individual characteristics may very well be correlated with both the labor supply decisions and the experience of wage arrears. We also allow the effect of first time wage arrears on the labor supply to be different from wage arrears in general. Such difference is important because it allows us to learn how people respond to repeated shocks such as wage arrears. We find that both husband and wife are more likely to take secondary informal job when they have wage arrears shocks in their primary jobs. Moreover, they are more likely to change their primary job after they experience wage arrears in their primary jobs. In the reduced form regression of household’s consumption on wage arrears, we find that the household consumption is very well protected from wage arrears shock. But the results in the structural equation shows that household consumption falls with the wage arrears shocks experienced by the wife. 7Labor force participation rate of women was 83.3%; 84.1%, 82.3%, 80.7% 78.7% and 78.9% in year 1994, 1995, 1996, 1998, 2000 and 2001 respectively. The labor force participation rate of men in the same period was 87.9%, 88.2%, 86.6%, 84.4%, 85.9% and 86.1%. (Mroz, Henderson, Bontch-Osmolovskii and Popkin, 2001) 64 The results suggest that overall insignificant effect of wage arrears on consumption reflects adjustment of secondary job holdings. The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the literatures on the causes of wage nonpayment in Russia and describe the features of wage arrears with descriptive statistics from RLMS. Section 3 presents the theoretical model of household labor supply with uncertainty and discusses the empirical specification strategy. Section 4 discusses the dataset used in the analysis. Section 5 presents the central results. Section 6 concludes. 2.2 Wage Arrears In Russia 2.2.1 The Causes of Wage Arrears Wage arrears in Russia are not an independent and isolated phenomenon. They were rather a part of more general and pervasive payment arrears, which included nonpayment from government to its suppliers in industries; nonpayment of tax from enterprise to government and nonpayment from enterprise to enterprise. All these arrears were to some extent inter-correlated in a vicious circle (Gimpelson and Lippoldt 2001; Ivanova and Wyplosz 1999). The causes of wage arrears and nonpayment in general have been the focus of many economic studies. At a macro level, tight monetary policy in the mid-19905 targeted at inflation is often cited as one possible root of nonpayment, because it induced economic depression and 65 cash shortages. Two features of fiscal policies during this period, high tax rates and budgetary cuts are also believed to have caused the wage arrears. High tax rates created incentives for firms to hide cash, while the budget cuts resulting from the budget deficit targets specified by the International Monetary Fund by the end of 1995 caused persistent underfinancing of the army as well as other public sectors and generated mass late wages and pensions. Absence of regulatory control also contributed to the widespread wage arrears, because it left firms managers with unchecked powers to manage money and unscrupulous managers were not held responsible for delaying or withholding wage payment to workers (Earle and Sabirianova 2002; Desai and Idson 2001;Gimpelson and Lippoldt 2001). In terms of firms’ decision regarding wage arrears at micro level, one interpretation is that wage arrears reflects an implicit contract between firms and employees. According to this theory, the firm proposes a contract that includes a low monetary wage and access to social service. The most productive workers leave the firm and concentrate in the most productive firms; the less adequate workers remain in their initial firm. In this framework, wage arrears can be viewed as an element of implicit contract between firms and less productive workers (Grosfeld et. 2001). Another View treats arrears as the outcome of generally poor economic performance of firms. Unprofitable firms lacking cash and run up arrears as a way for them to cut costs and stay afloat (Lehmann, Wadsworth and Acquisti 1999). This response may be especially attractive when firms face the political and bureaucratic obstacles to 66 layoffs, such as costly regulations and approvals that have to be met. Or managers may not want to create conflicts with local governments unwilling to allow large open unemployment (Commander et al. 1996). Wage arrears could also be a device used by managers to extract subsidies from the government, especially by firms with close ties to federal or local governments or those with greater bargaining power (Alfandari and Schaffer 1996). Given the decisions of firms with respect to wage arrears, Russian workers seem to have been very tolerant of such practices. Fear of unemployment might ex- plain why workers accept deteriorating employment conditions. It is particularly aggravated by the low level of unemployment benefits, which was also subject to arrears(Clarke 1998). At the same time, keeping an “old” job could provide at least some in-kind compensation, particularly enterprise-related social benefits, which include housing, nursery, health care and recreation benefits, and added about 5 percent to total labor costs in general 8. The larger the fringe benefit portion of compensation was, the stronger the incentives for workers to accept a backlog in wages (Gimpelson and Lippoldt 2001).Weak union is also cited as a factor leading to more wage arrears (Connor 1995). More importantly, when other firms in the region also pay late, the employees of a late-paying firm become less likely to quit, reduce effort or to strike. Such a self-propagation feature of the wage-arrear prac- 8The composition of fringe benefits in the Russian system is different than in the US. system. The fringe benefits in the US. include payments to private retirement systems as well as to life insurance, health benefits and other agreed-upon plans. Legally required payments such as Social Security and unemployment insurance contributions are normally not counted as the fringe benefits. Fringe benefits in the US. accounted for about 9.2%-l6.1% of total compensation in the 19805 (Woodbury 1983). 67 tice makes it difficult for workers not to accept wage arrears (Earle and Sabirianova 2000). 2.2.2 The Distributions of Wage Arrears on the Primary Jobs Official information on wage arrears in Russia is limited to aggregate levels of cumulative overdue wage debts. We use Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS) (1994-1996, 1998, 2000, 2001) micro level data to describe the magnitude, persistence and the distribution patterns of wage arrears on the primary jobs of the respondents. The incidence of wage arrears could be measured separately by two survey questions. The first one is “At the present time, does your primary place of work owe you any money which for some reasons they didn’t pay you on time?” This question measures the incidence of all wage arrears, which in Table 1 we call “owed wage ”. Since wage payment is very uncertain and workers got paid periodically, we also use the second question to measure the “flow ”of wage arrears. The respondent was asked “Tell me please, at your primary place of work in the last 30 days, did you get a sum of money as wages, bonuses, benefits, revenues, profits ? ”This question measures the incidence of wage arrears in the survey month and we name it “working without payment at current month ”. As we can see from Table 2.6, wage arrears have been prevalent over the years since early in the 1990’s. About 40% of respondents reported that they were owed 68 overdue wage at the survey dates in 1994 and 1995, with higher proportion for men than for women. The wage nonpayment rate rose to about 60% in 1996 and 64% at the time of financial crisis in 1998. During the period in which the economy was recovering from the financial crisis after 1998 , the rate of wage nonpayment dropped to 33.2% for men and 26% for women in 2000. It further decreased to 26.3% for men and 21.7% for women in 2001. Under the concept of wage arrears on the current month (3rd and 4th row of Table 2.6), the rate of wage nonpayment is lower than the rate measured by “whether currently owed money by the employer ”, because people who have wage arrears might choose to quit working or change jobs. Moreover, workers irregularly got repayment of back wages. The magnitude of arrears can be measured by “months of wages not paid ”. The average months of wage nonpayment was about 2.8 months in 1994 and rose to 6.0 months for men and 4.7 months for women in 1998. In 2000 and 2001, even though the incidence of wage arrears was much lower than previous years, the magnitude of wage nonpayment was not getting much better, with an average of 3 months in 2001. Variation of wage nonpayment across a number of individual characteristics was also large. Figure 1.1-Figure 4.2 depict the patterns of wage arrears by age, ed- ucation, tenure and relative monthly wage of individuals. The age effect (Figure 2.1 and 2.2) changes over the years, but for both men and women, young work- ers (age 18-29) are less likely to have wage arrears than older workers. Arrears 69 are generally negatively related to the level of education completed, especially for male workers (Figure 2.3 and 2.4). More educated workers are likely to have more alternative job prospects and thus less likely to continue working without payment at primary jobs. Workers with primary or less education were the most vulnerable to wage arrears, especially during the period of financial crisis in 1998. Tenure is generally positively related to the incidence of wage nonpayment (Figure 2.5 and 2.6). It might be explained by the fact that workers with long tenure might have less outside opportunity because of their specialized skills. New employees with tenure less than 1 year are far less likely to have wage arrears. The mobility cost for a new employee might be lower thus they are more likely to change job after nonpayment. Another explanation might be the fact that they were exposed to less incidence of wage arrears because of their short tenure with the employees. Figure 2.7 and 2.8 shows the relation between incidence of wage arrears and rela- tive real monthly earnings 9. They imply that people in the lower earning quartile have a higher incidence of wage arrears. The causality of wage arrears and wage earnings can go either way. Wage nonpayment may affect people at the bottom of wage distribution most if the managerial decision is to allocate wage arrears to the lower-paid, less-skilled employees (Desai and Idson 2001). On the other hand, wage arrears have negative effect on people’s earning and thus people who have wage nonpayment may be more likely to be in the bottom of the earning distribution. 9The survey doesn’t have the information on actual wage, instead it asked the respondent “How much money in the last 30 days did you receive from your workplace after taxes? ”. 70 Table 2.6 lists the wage arrears by occupation. In order to have enough observation numbers in each occupation-gender-year cell, we look at the distribution of wage nonpayment at the aggregate level, particularly before and after 1998. Consistent with the data in Table 2.6, there is a substantial drop in wage arrears in most of the occupations after 1998. Within each period there exists considerable variance, with rates ranging from 76.2% for men who are “agricultural and fishery laborers ”to 14.8% for “models, salespersons and demonstrators ”. The rate of wage non- payment is high in the semi-skilled job such as “machine operators and assemblers ”; or “drivers and mobile-plant operators ”. It is relatively low among profession- als like “general managers ”. This is consistent with the wage arrears distribution among different education categories displayed in Figure 2.1 and 2.2. Some fields such as “teaching professionals ”and “physical mathematical , engineering science professionals ”also experienced a high rate of wage arrears regardless of the high- level education of the employees. This phenomenon might be explained the fact that these jobs would fall under the budget sectors and government retrenchment in the late 1990’s increased the rate of wage nonpayment in these areas. Within each occupation, women are not necessarily less likely to get wage arrears although in general women have less incidence of wage arrears as showed in Table 2.6. 71 2.3 Theoretical Framework and Empirical Issues 2.3.1 Theoretical Framework This section examines how one might expect the likelihood of taking multiple job to vary with the experience of wage arrears in the primary job. Further, we explore the implication of multiple job holdings on household consumption decision. Households’ Choice of Multiple Job Holdings We begin by considering a simple theoretical model of a household’s choice of leisure and consumption. An analysis of households’ choice of multiple job holdings involves the specification of a model under uncertainty whereby observed choice depends on households’ wage payment in primary jobs, thus the realization of the wage arrears shock. Assume households exist until time T and their utility function depends on household total consumption C as well as the leisure of male and female household head. The leisure is represented by discrete choice variable im and if, each of which stands for male and female member’s choice on multiple job holding. Let the wage of male and female household head in primary job be WMm and WMf. The realization of their wage arrears shock in the primary job is represented by P3,! and PIM’ And we denote the nonpecuniary benefits that are associated with having the primary job by B. If male or female household head chooses to take multiple jobs (im = lor if = 1), we assume they can get wage payment 72 W5", and st at the non-primary job(s) without risk. The households’ objective function at any point of the life cycle is then described by the maximization of the expected utility subject to the budget constraint: 1 T MaxUt = EtZWU(CT’lmT’lth) (2.1) T=t At = (1+ 7‘)At—1 — Ct—l + WMmt1(PMmt=1)+ WMft1(PMft = 1) + + Wsmtl(imt =1)+ WSft1(ift=1)+ B CT = AT (2.2) where 1(.) is the indicator function of the event between brackets—for instance, “male household head taking multiple jobs period t ”is 1(imt = 1) = 1 Because PMmt = 1 and PM ft = 1 refer to the male and female household head getting full wage payment at primary job in period t, we can write the probability of full wage payment as the following: PT(P1Wmt = 1) = Et[1(PMmt = 1)] = Pmt; (pmt 6 [0,1]) (2.3) and Pr m0 325 was moseanH ”mm meB 99 —c»— age 18-29 —e— age 30-39 -- —o- - , age 40-49 — - — - age 50-60 19’94 1ng 1996 19'98 2600 2061 year Figure 2.1: Currently Owed Wage by Age (Men) —o—— age 18—29 _._._.,__ age 30-39 .. - age 4049 — — — — age 50-55 19’94 19’95 19’96 19'98 2600 2061 year Figure 2.2: Currently Owed Wage by Age (Women) 100 —e— university and above—s— sp_ecial secondary .. _e— — . general secondary - — — — primary and less 19'94 19‘95 19% 1698 2o'oo 2061 year Figure 2.3: Currently Owed Wage by Education (Men) —e— university and abov<+e— special secondary .. —e —- general secondary - — — — pnmary and less \§?\\: 7 ‘ ‘D \ RX 2 1 \ 19'94 19’95 19'96 19198 2050 2003 year Figure 2.4: Currently Owed Wage by Education (Women) 101 —e— tenure: <1 year —.rr— tenure: 1-10 years ~ -0 — tenure: 10-20 years— — — — tenure: >20 years 1094 1905 1906 1908 2000 2001 year Figure 2.5: Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Men) -—e—— tenure: <1 year —e— tenure: 1-10 years -- —0 — tenure: 10-20 years— — — - tenure: >20 years 1904 1095 1906 1908 2000 2001 year Figure 2.6: Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Women) 102 —+>— wage: 1st quartile —.~e—— wage: 2nd quartile .. —e — wage: 3rd quartile — — - — wage: 4th quartile .8“ 1994 1995 1996 1998 2000 2001 year Figure 2.7: Currently Owed Wage by Wage (Men) —e~— wage: 1st quartile _.._. wage: 2nd quartile .5 —D- — wage: 3rd quartile — — — — wage: 4th quartile .,\‘ \ U \ .— 19'94 1995 1996 1998 2000 2001 year Figure 2.8: Currently Owed Wage by Tenure (Women) 103 104 Anaev Ame:v Toemv Amemv 83 8:8 8:8 :88 :8 85888.: 8888. 8:0 Away A88 Amemv A88 888 8 888 82 :8 2829.85 2888. 8288 :88 :8 A88 88 :8 88892: $888. 83 8:8 88 88 :28: use 88:8 as :88 :88 :88 :88 :8 88832: 83 88 N88 888 3882 858 8:858: :08 8293a :88 $8 :88 :88 8982 .883 8883.88: 88:88 83 8:8 83. 8.88 :8 88888: $50 Av:mv Toma Tampa TowHV 82 88 88 :88 :8 seesseea 8298:. AmeHV Acav AHOMV “88:8 83 88 8:8 88 :8 289885 88: as 85:8 a: 88 88 A88 :88 :8 aeeeaeea 88 :88 88 8.8.8 8:98 8:858: 8988882 888: Amo:8 A888 AeCHV A:mmv N88 23 888 83 :8 5882 8580 A88 :88 a: :8 :38 5882 828.50 :88 88 88 888 .8880 888 888:8: A88 A888 AQHV Aem:v :8 8:8 88 8.8 :8 see: 888 3:8 :osmasooo 0.: £388 5:83 :22 5835 :22 308880 3:288:80 88 as? 88 seem: Awmmfi aefiieaomonv :ofiaasooo 3 Emmet/x ewm>> ”Wm 23:9 an: Ed 38 88 at 88 as 88 $803 $3 88 :3 38 2: $8 $5 38 5s 38 so: 88 83 :8 88: 88 am; 88 8a 88 a: 88 Go: 88 88 $5 88 E; 28 $9 88 A8: 88 av 3a 88 :3 88 £8 88 8: 88 A3 88 5803 A8: 88 SE 88 2: 88 88V 88 38V 88 a5 88 SE 88 65 88 38V 8.8 6.3 88 83 88 :32 Ammmfiv :8 38V 88 0.3 88 :8 88 83 88 av 88 33 :8 38 mumEEmmmao. was muouwhmao 2:382 C8 @5885 BEEmanOOBJSmEH 83330 paflm$uwaosfim Ackvnzflsxmfimumfiob woo? $58805 woo: 8810.3 8989 Umpflom 98 £80 550 at 285$ 885 95 £388: .aoEBBL 88 858:8 0d 86-3 fowvudo 3:283:80 Amt 8&8?» @2382 98 :3on St 88103 $ng wEEBm Una aoBQmem A848 £883 827,; 28 8330:? 33m 33 macaaSmaoEmQ was mcoflmamofimimvoz 232383 835m @388on «Ed 3:885 Amvv £85 838m 58890 Ad; 8120 8&0 .5803 8 289 105 .flmofififida E $539,530 mo :55: Z .3833”?32.3263 355 Essa: asasxwafi Ewan 528m 68 m2 Gm: awed 3va 33 :5 :3 83v £2. at Swd A33 ammo 3% $2 33 Ed $5 .83 8mg 23 2m: and :wmv 82 a: $3 933 93.0 prmfiv wood 33 fioamafib ,wstsuofisawz 50535300 .wEEE E $2093 $8805an 5935 EB Ehsfisothx szwfigflo osmmfiovfiovsg 88$ mqoswazooo mausofiflm mmomimm Una 83m Amwzmafio Baggage, 883 88230 EaE-=noE 98 Egta .929; mm 2an 106 4832:5me 8985:2888 8.8: .1: 8:3 8: «EH 888558888 5 28 £85 @3qu5 888.8 88.8 :88 88.8 88.8 :88 888.8 88.8 888.8 8888 88:88 85828 828 8888 8888 888 8:8 888 888 888 f .I 8:8 888 8:5 388 88:20 :88 888.8 88.8 888.8 28.8 888.8 :88 888.8 88.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888 888 8888 828 888 828 :88 828 8:8 888 888 888 888858 82 :88 888.8 88.8 888.8 :88 888.8 :88 888.8 88.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 8888 8888 888 888 888 :88 88.8 888 8888 8888 8.8.8 8888 813888888 8888 888.8 888.8 888.8 288.8 888.8 988.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 8888 A8 .85 88. 888 888 888 8888 888 8888 8888 8888 888 888 888 8888 88:85 8 888888 8888 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 88. 82:88 888 8888 888 :88 8888 888 888 8888 888 888 888 888 8888888 8 885:8! 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 288.8 888.8 888.8 288.8 288.8 288.8 288.8 888 88.88 888888 8 88 8888 888 888 888 8888 8888 8888 8888 8888 8888 8888 8888 88.58 8888888 8 888:8 I 8888 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 88. 88.58 888 :88 888 888 8888 888 888 888 8888 888 888 888 888888 8 888:8 I 8888 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 8.888 888.8 888 888 £88 888 8888 8888 8888 8888 888 888 8888 :88 88 88. 885:8 l :88 88.8 :88 88.8 88.8 :88 :88 88.8 :88 888.8 888.8 888.8 888 8888 88.8 888 58 8888 888 888 8888 8888 88.8 8888 E 888 88:88 8 B88888. magnum enmahoagm 88> 88888 88> 85.8.88 88> 88888: 88> 888888 88> 888888 88> 8882.8 888 8888 8888 8888 8888 =< 85> 8:8 853832 mo magnum uamfizofiam mo nossntuma «Mm 858% 107 $888.8 $888.8 #8888 I888 :88 8888 8888 888 888 8888 888 8888 888 88888888 8.885 88.8 I I I 1888 £838 £85. 888 I I I 888 8888 m88> 888 88> 82.8 888.8 $888.8 8,888.8 88.8 888.8 88.2 888.8 88.2 38.2 88.2 888.2 888888 8.885 #8888 1.88.8 #8888 1888.8 1888.8 888.8 88.88 82.8 8.888 88.88 88.88 8.888 888. 8.88> 8,888.8 8,888.8 :8888 $888.8 $888.8 $8888 88. 83:88 888 8888 8888 8888 E88 888 8888888 888 888.88 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 88. 8888 888 888 888 :88 888 8888 8888888 888 858888 £88.: $888.8 888.8 88.8 $888.8 $888.8 88: 8882 888.88 83: 8283 8882 88882 88883 38. 8.88288 $888.8 $888 #8888 $888.8 $8888 $888 8888 8888 888 888 8888 888 838 8888888 8.88.38: 88.8 I $88.8 .1888 I | 8882 :88 I 8888 8888 I I 8885 888 888888 88.8 88.8 888.8 888.8 188.8 8.8888 88.88 888.8 888.9 88.2 88888 888.2 888888 8.88288 $888 I888 888 8.8.8 $888.8 1,888.8 8888 888.8 88888 88.8 838 888.8 88.8 8.8888: mudmuu< mempu/x mud®uu< 033 BE om8>> 8m mummt< 888.18 8.822% ow8>> 88> 5 88> 8 mum88> 8888> 888 88> 88: 88 852 88388 85888 88; 88> $52 88> 8888:: 893888 £88.58 mw8>> an 80583308830 203$:on 93 126365 N: @388 108 .732 endomemm “RS 98 88m 88 5:28 ”.5353 59c 85:56 3.283338“ u. 98 3 .EBfiqflwa E fiche «8.8855 5qu $38888t8888888 1888888 :88888 88.888 88.888 8888 88:8: 8888888 88888 88.8888 8.8888 882 8888 88:8 :33 88888 8888 88.8: 88888 888.28 88888 8.23 888:: 88.23 88888: 88.82 8:88 88882 88888 888.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 888.8 88.8 828 828 828 888 828 828 8885 888 8 88882 888.8 :88 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 888 8888 888 888 :88 888 58 888 8 88882 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 :88 88.8 5885 8.8 8: 883 82 883 82 883 88883 8 88882 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 88.8 888 83 83 8:8 8:8 882 882 8:8 8:883 8 8852 £888 i838 $888.8 1.88.8 .1888 1888.8 88 88 8 888 88388 888 888 8888 8888 888 88.8 88880 8 88882 1.888 188.8 $88.8 $888 :888 1.88.8 8888 88.8 8888 8888 888 58 8.88880 8 8852 8.88.8 888.8 #8888 1,888.8 :8888 5.8888 88. 88:88 888 888 8888 888 8888 888 8888888 88 88> L888 1888.8 $888.8 #8888 888.8 888.8 88. 88:88 888 :88 888 888 8888 8888 8888888 88: 83> $888.8 188.8 188.: 8.88.8 888.8 82.8 888 88: 8888 88.5 88.88 88.888 88.88 8:883 888. p88> 8.888 8.8 888. 109 82. 58288 888: 85> non iwwsooom mezzo: $85533 288.8 688.8 288.8 $8.8 $8.8 58.8 858.? 88.8 888. 888. 38.9- 880.9- @885 882-82 Amos 5388 588.8 2.288 689.8 858.8 658.8 888 588 888 28.8 :88- :88- M85> 8 8? 328.8 838.8 888.8 388.8 888.8 888.8 583- 3:8- 85.8 853 $28 88.8 85> 8 83 $558.8 £3588 £9588 888.8 288.8 858.8 38.8 $8.? 88.? 28.8 888. 28.8- 28825 8 83 32:58 £858 $3858 5588 588.8 358.8 882 SS; 88: 583 SS: 283 888:: 8 a? 65.8 52.8 $82.8 $82.8 28:8 25:8 33 $88 388 $88 883 £88 m85> 8 82.83% $2.8 @828 A828 82.8 33.8 83.8 88.0- £88- 33¢. ”:38 8:3 888 2.388 8 82885 328.8 588.8 $288 $88 3088 888.8 ma5>l 8:3 :83 882. 8.8.8 853- 88.8. .885. 85> 88> 3858 A858 8588 58.8 85.8 $288 2888:! 583. 82$ 8:8 583- «god- 88.8 285. 85> E; m m H m m H 28288 «8wa SEE >35 8 Son. Eavaooom wEEomv omcoammm .5qu mo coSwEEmm— QESQ 809:3 ”Wm £an 110 83:55: :omww:\8w.m 3:“ Ewhbmzuowaué: mm? :5 @5353 “o 33 “Ed :03835 3333 3333:“ m23£3> 555558 @833 35* 355558 m3: 5 :53 555588 23 3 38.0 >588 u:m::::w>ow§£:5:58 m3» an 835% u:m:§o~9:w€_o3om:o3 033 :3 :2:\:o:83 £32m .30 53:5: $3... 6303503 $33 :3 5503\55 mww wEvtoB 30 83:5: m3» 6.030953 v3... :3 SA. .30 owm am 55:30 .30 53:5: 2: "2039503 23 :3 ed 30 www an 55:30 .30 83:5: 333:3 3:252:55 3535-55 mo 0?:wa 23 25 aomwmouwm: m3... 5 @2535 85338, 5380 .m 332 $3 am 5.85%6 .396— oAh am 550$:wmwi £83535: 5 Ba :85 “555% awn—30¢: Elam onmm Emm Emm onmm cpmm 30 .30 53:52 mmvd movd 3.2 3.2 35.3 ms; :85on «32. Game 885 85.8 Ewe- mwmd mmvd wwfifi 2.2 awzé Std- 802.3 33o vmvd mwvd 53>: 833555 3:55:55 3.2 5.3 3:2:8/5838 we vwfio>< 853$:me 55H om>>lm5mt< owa>>x ~858st @833 wqw3msmlm$mb< mw§>x :os‘mozvm 983$ oh>>lu£dmh< www>>x :os‘mgvm m.v:m3m=m v:m3m:mlm8mt< mwm>>x 5585a M58353 Ammmfi .8 £§>Ium5wt< mwm H .o- “~wa x gamma: So: .8 @53m:mlm5ob< unwed www>> x macaw/V. 5.88 :omaomumu:m .5203 3 2a: 111 30w ESEOBW 3:203 @333 33. 5358mm wEEom £5535: :88 :88 58.8 €88 $8.8 $8.8 Soo- oooo- ooooo- oooo- oooo- ooooo- @883 Sosaoz $08 38.8 38.8 :ooo8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 oooo oooo voooo Hooo- Hooo- ooooo- ers o0 no? :38 638 @968 :38 88.8 83:8 vowo- oooo- goo- oooo Hooo ozoo 35> oo o? $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 $8.8 fioo- :oo- ozoo- Hooo- Boo- fiooo- 3825 o0 No? 1.33.8 1688 £558 :38 38.8 $398 on: 83 oooo: no; vodo 52o oooomom oo o? 32.8 82.8 85.8 :38 6:8 5:8 oooo oooo ooooo oooo aoo ooooo as: oo 838:8 $2.8 3:8 A338 :28 2:8 33:8 oooo- oooo- goo- :oo oooo- voooo- 288:; o0 838%: £828 £328 Looodoo $2.8 $2.8 2:28 mos/I opoo «So 38o oooo- ovoo- goo- $22 owes :88 82.8 $8.8 $2.8 328 8:28 Esmoml vooo- o2.o voto moo vooo ooooo $22 owes o o H o m H m5mb< momma 3 A33. >53:oomm 9:22.: om:o:mom 5353 Moo :oSmEEmm £38m EovSWm ”9m 2358 112 83:55: :o_wo:\8mm 358 88583838.: or? 3:8 358353 mo wwm :8 :2858 3:3 3838835 8388:, 33:55:80 883: :8 5:55:80 83» 8 :83 «33:55:80 83» 8 8.88 8088 585853955558 83» 8 83:8 58539586338503 83: :3 55:58:83 3820 80 83:5: 83: €_o3mm503 m3: 5 8503\85 ow: m:283 mo 83:5: 83: “2038803 83... 5 SA. mo .88 8 :8239 Ho 83:5: 83» 63038503 83... :3 3.0 we mm: .8 85:8 .30 83:5: 833.28.» 38398985 3853.855 mo 8888 833 8.8 806888 83» :_ 8:305 8582.? 8330 .m .88— voS .8 3:83:86 «883 Km 8 5805881 28588: :3 88 30:8 583588 853363 Emm 3mm onmm oumm 05mm ommm 30 mo 83:52 mmvd movd amvd mmvd vmvd cmvd 8387: 833853 558855 8.2 $2 moo: m2: No.2 83: 85:18:80 woos; "8:805:9m 55H $3.8 om>>lm88u< owa>>x wwod- :ofiwosvm 98:3 * 1.38.8 $3.8 v83m5mlw882< owa>>x mid mad :omowoscm 98:? 38.8 mm>>lm88u< .835 x mvod- :oSmofium $58385 38835318883. momma x 838:3 £88353; 38.8 28.8 mm>>lum8mh< owed mood- 882/ x mummmaq. 88.8 93.8 v:m3m:mlm8m:< mnod mood- wwaXmommm< EhmeL ”OmHUGhmuflH 8:88 oo 228 113 fig 3532: $36: $35 383 158385 53233 £53352 $83 6333 $8.3 $8.3 $8.3 $8.3 . 283 383 2:5 883. $8.3 $8.? 2:85 522-82 303 $8.3 $8.3 $8.3 $8.3 $8.3 238.3 553 383 $83 883 883 883 3:5 30 my? 2233 8333 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 33.3 23.3 3.33 333 335 3:5 .6 a? .2383 238.3 .2383 $8.3 $8.3 $83 383. 38.0- 383. :83- £83- :83- 28%: mo 33. $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 233.3 3.3.: $2: 3%.: some- 52- 33.3 288: mo .3 $2.3 $5.3 $5.3 $8.3 $8.3 $83 332:. 333 :33 383 383 3:3 35> 30 838:5 $2.3 $2.3 $23 8333 $333 $333 283 283 28.0 wowed $83 $23 289: Mo 858%: $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $33 .327 :33 333 33... 28.3 883. 383 $85. .833 ii $3.3 $3.3 $33 .2333 .2533 .2333 955:! 32.0- 33.3 333. 333 833 33.0 322 was: Ea m m H m m H 3885. 8.335 8:38 8:5 3 $83 338385 wEEomv 8503833 .8353 .30 :oSaESmm— £38m 503533 ”Nam 233B 114 wflEfiSv somwmuidw» ES Ewhbmzuowmmt v33 «:8 @539: mo 33 98 .8382? at? 88335 moEfig 5:55:80 39: 98 5:58:80 23 3 x53 chains—Eco 23 am @320 @308 pamEEm>ow55588 23 as 83.8w EmEhOEEoqunmvE—o: m5 5 5E\=oEoB bumEm m0 835:: 2: ”29395: 23 E 5803\58 ow“ music? m0 538:: 23 ”20:34:03 2: E 3.» mo wwm am 5:55 Mo .8855 on» ”203820: 2: E oé mo mwa aw 56:5 “0 82,5: 333:; anmvsomvwfi undigéfis .«0 $9295 23 m3 3063“me 23 E 39:05 81153 850 .m .35: $2 pa Edowfiwmm 392 gm an endowmzwwmi £85553 5 was E85 Eavsfim awn—pom; oumm 05mm opmm 3mm 2mm 05mm 30 Mo 53832 coed mocd 8.: No.3 €33 33¢- $3.3 38d- $3.3 Seed game 286 need Sad No.2 9&2 $8.8 an: 8398 v83 83 no; 2:33 853:3 aqvvqwamvfl EaES/éEwH mo mwfim>< "8:505:me ”Ewen. maglmammhxx www>>x 858va Emma vqgmzmlfiaohax wwm>>x :oEwosvm mbfia oralmfimmbaa www>> x 338:3“ $95333 vawnmsmlfi‘mobx‘ mwaa x cosmozvm M65525 «5.3 no.2 60...... H .8 mm>>|m5mb< owmod owa>> x meomm< Ammofi .8 finanmsmlmuaot< unwed mw§> x mummm< "mEuoH. :omuowuoacm .5283 S 03% 115 foe 3:833 wagon $83 x88 EEmEoE wEEom 98:83:: 68.8 38.8 88.8 88.8 85.8 823.8 83 83 $83 :3- :3- :83- ESE 80.2-82 808 $8.8 388 A888 $8.8 $8.8 $88 83 83 R83 883 883 883 8:5 8 83 $38 888 A838 $8.8 $88 6838 83- 383- 883- 83 83 883 85> 8 a? ...,:88 $988 ...388 88.8 :88 88.8 23- 383- 883- 83- 83- 283- 888m 30 mm? 68.8 388 $38 88.8 88.8 58.8 82 83 as: 83- 83- 3:3. 288m 8 88. 8:8 3:8 A828 £88 888 A888 83 E3 883 83 23 883 85> 8 8:853 8:8 328 3:38 £88 :88 838 R3- 83- 883- 83 383 :83 828m mo 888% 32.2.8 3,338 ......§8.8 82.8 :28 33:8 oral 83 83 883 83 83 383 £85. 083 $28 82.8 8838 £28 £838 638 288ml 33 :3- 383 83 83 823 $22 $83 3 m H m m H $58.18 «3wa on. 333 1388205 wEEomv mmcoammm 5qu mo :oBaESmm 85on Sow—Em uwN @388 116 885:6 somwouiavh 98 Emhbmzaommmfiu wt? «:8 finanmsn mo wma 98 :ompwosvw :33 330835 8535? 3:55:50 v85 98 3358800 2: pa x55 £35888 2: am @820 iouofl azoghgomwbazfifioo 23 an 835m 35880353303850: 2: E :oE\:mEoB 352m we 53:5: 0:... ”20596: «.5 E 5503\55 emu wanton, mo 85:5: 2: ”20:03.03 25 5 5A. mo awn am 55:40 .«0 .8285: 2: ”22385: 2: 5 ed mo mww pm Etc—Eu mo .8355: 833:3 acvvcmamvfi unamgéfifi «o mwfiozm 2: 2w maommmemmz 2: E 89:05 83£8> 550 .m .732 0&3 ad unwoficwfi «:32 “Nb 3 undocfimii £85588 5 was $0th 6:6:ng 885,3: onmm onmm onmm Emm Emm onmm Bo mo 83:52 nwmd ommd 38¢ mgd mmvd :vd @3878 853:3 uaqumaovfi mmg 8.: 3.2 3.2 wag 922 ESE>¢§B mo mwSo>< ”853$:me ”Ewen. 88.8 83>lm8mb< www>>x owed- ~838sz Mora 23.8 @canmsmlflawt< owa>>x Sod 833sz work, $8.8 ark/[85:48 «3wa x vood ”~330sz Mvamnmsm Ammodv vamnmsmlmuwouhm mwa>> x v8.0- 358va @9533: 8.88 E88 088L522 wmod- mwod oma>>x$omm< $8.8 $8.8 cgnmsmlfldmbxx Sod- wmod- wwwzwxfimwm< umEHmH—r QOmHONHQHQH .3258 3 28.8 117 Table 2.9: Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Change of Job) to First Wage Arrears Husband’s Wife’s Change of Job Change of Job 1 2 1 2 First Time Wage Arrears 0.029 0.029 0.045 0.050 in Previous Period—Husband (0.166) (0.167) (0.187) (0.188) First Time Wage Arrears -0.021 -0.021 0.241 0.244 in Previous Period—Wife (0.163) (0.173) (0.174) (0.173) Education of Husband 0.025 0.027 0.003 0.005 (0.055) (0.057) (0.059) (0.080) Education of Wife 0.023 0.021 -0.023 -0.014 (0.057) (0.054) (0.063) (0.066) Age of Husband -0.313 -0.341 0.271 -0.271 (0.344) (0.344) (0.373) (0.374) Age2 of Husband -0.001 -0.001 0.002 0.002 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Age of Wife 0.326 -0.316 0.374 0.371 (0.366) (0.363) (0.405) (0.405) Age2 of Wife —0.001 -0.002 -0.005 -0.005 (0.004) (0.007) (0.004) (0.005) (log) Non-labor Income —0.016 -0.023 -0.032 -0.031 (0.014) (0.012)* (0.015)M (0.014)" 118 Table 2.9 (cont’d). Interaction Terms: Husband’s Educationx First Time Wage Arrears—Husband Husband’s Educationx First Time Wage Arrears—Wife 0.023 (0.012)* -o.oo3 (0.026) Wife’s Educationx 0.024 First Time Wage Arrears~—Husband (0.033) Wife’s Educationx -0.039 First Time Wage Arrears—Wife (0.034) Joint Significance: Average of Time-Variant 120.82 120.71 69.54 69.33 Independent Variables p—value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Number of obs. 2617 2617 2617 2617 1.Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. level. "significant at 5% level;* significant at 10% 2.0ther variables included in the regressions are the average of time-variant independent variables number of children at age of 0-6 in the household; the number of children at age of 7-17 in the household; the number of working age men/ women in the household; the number of elderly women/ men in the household; employment service at the community; government factory closed at the community, bank at the community, and these community variables interacted with education and age of husband and wife respectively; year and year/ region dummies. 119 Table 2.10: Random Probit Estimation of Labor Response (Change of Job) to Wage Arrears Husband’s Wife’s Change of Job Change of Job 1 2 1 2 Wage Arrears in Previous Period 0.270 0.271 -0.063 -0.070 —Husband (0.096)” (0.091)" (0.109) (0.109) Wage Arrears in Previous Period -0.082 -0.082 -0.096 -0.087 ——Wife (0.098) (0.098) (0.111) (0.111) Education of Husband 0.022 0.024 0.003 0.005 (0.055) (0.057) (0.060) (0.059) Education of Wife 0.027 0.027 -0.024 -0.015 (0.057) (0.058) (0.063) (0.066) Age of Husband -0.346 -0.346 -0.291 -0.291 (0.345) (0.345) (0.371) (0.371) Age2 of Husband -0.0004 -0.0004 0.002 0.002 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Age of Wife 0.334 0.334 0.411 0.408 (0.368) (0.368) (0.403) (0.404) Age2 of Wife -0.0002 -0.0002 -0.005 -0.005 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (log) Non-labor Income -0.017 -0.017 -0.032 -0.039 (0.014) (0.014) (0.015)" (0.015)” 120 Table 2.10 (cont’d). Interaction Terms: Husband’s Educationx 0.024 Wage Arrears—Husband (0.057) Husband’s Educationx 0.027 Wage Arrears—Wife (0.058) Wife’s Educationx 0.022 Wage Arrears—Husband (0.033) Wife’s Educationx -0.039 Wage Arrears—Wife (0.034) Joint Significance: Average of Time-Variant 120.63 120.54 69.01 68.66 Independent Variables p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Number of obs 2617 2617 2617 2617 1.Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. “significant at 5% level;* significant at 10% level. 2.0ther variables included in the regressions are the average of time-variant independent variables number of children at age of 0-6 in the household; the number of children at age of 7-17 in the household; the number of working age men /women in the household; the number of elderly women / men in the household; employment service at the community; government factory closed at the community, bank at the community, and these community variables interacted with education and age of husband and wife respectively; year and year/ region dummies. 121 Table 2.11: Consumption Regression (First Time Arrears) Reduced Structure Form Equation Fixed Ef— Fixed Ef- fect fect Estimation IV Esti- mation First Time Wage Arrears -0.051 -0.026 —Husband (0.039) (0.042) First Time Wage Arrears -0.035 -0.048 —Wife (0.041) (0.045) Secondary Job Holding 0.699 —Husband (0.251)“ Secondary Job Holding 0.336 ———Wife (0.215) Age of Household Head —0.048 -0.050 (0.032) (0.034) Number of Male Children -0.200 -0.190 (<18 years old) (0.027)“ (0.029)“ Number of Female Children -0.124 -0.126 (<18 years old) (0.022)“ (0.024)“ Number of Working Age Male -0.107 -0.097 (age 1860) (0.030)“ (0.032)“ Number of Working Age Female -0.101 -0.118 (age 1855) (0.031)“ (0.033)“ Number of Senior Male 0.033 0.070 (260 years old) (0.089) (0.095) Number of Senior Female -0.216 -0.214 (255 years old) (0.051)“ (0.057)“ No-Labor Income 0.009 0.009 (0.003)“r (0.003)“ Number of obs 3570 3570 F(78,2510) 7.16 Wald chi2(80) 936246.45 1.Standard errors are in parenthesis. “significant at 5% level;* significant at 10% level. 2. Other variables included in the regressions are the year and year/ region dummies 122 Table 2.12: Consumption Regression (Wage Arrears) Reduced Form Structure Equation Fixed Effect Fixed Effect Estimation IV Estimation Wage Arrears 0.025 -0.028 -—Husband (0.029) (0.034) Wage Arrears -0.047 -0.088 —Wife (0.029)* (0.032)“ Secondary Job Holding 0.726 —Husband (0.383)* Secondary Job Holding 0.725 —Wife (0.323)”r Age of Household Head -0.107 -0.119 (0.051)“ (0.054)“ Number of Male Children -0.257 -0.264 (<18 years old) (0.038)“ (0.041)” Number of Female Children -0.135 -0.152 (<18 years old) (0.029)“ (0.032)“ Number of Working Age Male -0.126 -0.108 (age 18—60) (0.037)“ (0.041)“ Number of Working Age Female -0.109 -0.163 (age 18-55) (0.038)“ (0.044)“ Number of Senior Male 0.025 -0.008 (260 years old) (0.114) (0.126) Number of Senior Female -0.170 -0.158 (255 years old) (0.062)“ (0.076)“ No—Labor Income 0.011 0.009 (0.004)“ (0.004)“ Number of obs 3570 3570 F(78,2510) 4.87 Wald chi2(80) 675238.84 1.Standard errors are in parenthesis. "significant at 5% level;* significant at 10% level. 2. Other variables included in the regressions are the year and year/ region dummies 123 BIBLIOGRAPHY Alfandar, G. and M. E. Schaffer (1996), “‘Arrears ’in the Russian Enterprise Sector, ”Enterprise Restructuring and Economic Policy in Russia ed. Commander, S., Q. Fan, and ME. Schaffer, Washington DC. World Bank. Bellman, R. (1957), Dynamic Programming Princeton, N .J .: Princeton University Press. Blundell, R. and T. MaCurdy (1999), “Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches, ” Handbook of Labor Economics Volume 3, ed. O. Ashenflter and D.Card. Blundell, Richard, T. Magnac and C. Meghir (1997), “Savings and Labor-Market 'Iiansitions, ”Journal of Business 85 Economic Statistics Volume 15, No.2: 153-164. Clarke, S. (1998), Structural Adjustment Without Mass Unemployment?: Lessons from Russia Northampton, Mass: E.Elgar. Commander, S., S. Dhar, and Y. Ruslan (1996), “How Russian Firms Make Their Wage and Employment Decision, ” Enterprise Restructuring and Economic Policy in Russia ed. S.Commander, Q. Fan, and M. E. Schaffer, Washington DC. World Bank. Desai, P. and T. Idson (2000), Work Without Wages— Russia’s Nonpayment Crisis The MIT press. Desai, P. (2000), “Why did the Ruble Collapses in August 1998?,” The American Economic Review 90.2: 48-52. Earle, J. S., and K. Z. Sabirianova (2002), “How Late to Pay? Understanding Wage Arrears in Russia, ”Journal of Labor Economics v20, n3: 661-707. Foley, M. C.(1997), “Labor Market Dynamics In Russia,” Economic Growth Center, Yale UniversityCenter Discussion Paper No.780. 124 ’ Gimpelson, V., and D. Lippoldt (2001), The Russian Labor Market: Between Transition and Turmoil Lanham, Md. and Oxford: Rowman and Littlefield. Grosfel, I. S., T. Verdier, S. Kolenikov, and E, Paltseva (2001), “Workers’ Heterogeneity and Risk Aversion: A Segmentation Model of the Russian Labor Market, ”Journal of Comparative Economics 29: 230-256. Heckman, J. J., and T. E. MaCurdy (1980), “A Life Cycle Model of Female Labour Supply, ”Review of Economic Studies 49: 659-660. Honoré, B. E. (1992), “Trimmed Lad and Least Squares Estimation of Truncated and Censored Regression in Models with Fixed Effects, ” Econometrica 13: 533-565. Jensen, R., and K. Richter (2002), “Social Security, Income Volatility and Health: Evidence from The Russian Pension Crisis ”Working Paper. Kochar, A. (1999), “Smoothing consumption by smoothing income: hours-or-work responses to idiosyncratic agricultural shocks in rural India, ”Review of Economics and Statistics Vol. 81(1): 50-61. Koumakhov, R., and N. Boris (2001), “Labor Hoarding in Russia: Where Does It Come From?,” William Davidson Institute at the University of Michigan Business School Working paper 394. Lehmann, H., J. Wadsworth, and A. Acquisti (1999), “Crime and Punishment: Job Insecurity and Wage Arrears in the Russian Federation, ”Journal of Comparative Economics v22, n4: 595-617. Lugovoy, O. (2002), “Arrears In A Titansition Economy: The Mechanism of Contagion, ”RECEP working paper. Lundberg, S. (1985), “The Added Worker Effect, ”Journal of Labor Economics Vol. 3, Issue 1: 11-37. MaCurdy, T. E.(1985), “Interpreting Empirical Models of Labor Supply in an Intertemporal Framework with Uncertainty, ”Longitudinal Analysis of Labor Market Data ed. J. Heckman and B. Singer, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 125 Mackenzie, D. J. (2003a), “Aggregate Shocks and Labor Market Responses: Evidence from Argentinas Financial Crisis, ”CREDPR Working Paper No. 176, forthcoming, Economic Development and Cultural Change. Mackenzie, D. J. (2003b), “How do Households Cope with Aggregate Shocks? Evidence from the Mexican Peso Crisis, ” World Development 31(7): 1179-99. Mroz, T., L. Henderson, and B. Popkin (2001), “Monitoring Economic Conditions in Russian Federation: The Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey 1992-2000, ”Report submitted to the US. Agency for International Development. Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, North Carolina. Mroz, T., B. Osmolovsii, and B. Popkin (2002), “Monitoring Economic Conditions in Russian Federation: The Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey 1992-2001, ”Report submitted to the US. Agency for International Development. Carolina P0pulation Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, North Carolina. Rose, E. (2001), “Ex ante and ex post labor supply response to risk in a low—income area, ”Journal of Development Economics Vol. 64: 371-388. Russian Economic Trends Working Center for Economic Reform, Government of the Russian Federation. London,U.K.: Whurr Publishers. Various issues 1999-2002. Smith, J. P., D. Thomas, E. Frankenberg, K. Beegle, and G. Teruel (2002), “Wages, employment and economic shocks: Evidence from Indonesia, ”Journal of Population Economics 15: 161-93. Spletzer, J. R. (1997), “Reexamining the Added Worker Effect,” Economic Inquiry Vol.XXXV: 417-427. Stephens, M. Jr.(2002), “Worker Displacement and the Added Worker Effect,” Journal of Labor Economics v20, n3: 504-537. Woodbury, S. A. (1983), “Substitution Between Wage and Nonwage Benefits, ”The American Economic Review 73:166-182. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002) Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data MIT press: Cambridge, MA. 126 APPENDIX Table 2.13: First Stage Regression of Multiple Job Holdings Husband Taking Secondary Job Wife Taking Secondary Job Presence of Community -0.071 -0.116 Employment Service Center (0.210) (0.252) Employment Service Center 0.029 Interacted with Husband’s Education (0.014)" Employment Service Center 0.036 Interacted with Wife’s Education (0.018)“ Age of Household Head -0.019 -0.011 (0.003)" (0.004)" Number of Male Children -0.043 -0.259 (118 years old) (0.128) (0.159) Number of Female Children -0.158 -0.042 (118 years old) (0.074)” (0.100) Number of Working Age Male 0.034 -0.088 (age 18—60) (0.045) (0.052)* Number of Working Age Female 0.053 0.064 (age 18-55) (0.029)* (0.033)* Number of Senior Male -0.040 0.008 (g,=60 years old) (0.059) (0.067) Number of Senior Female 0.046 0.034 (1,=55 years old) (0.058) (0.067) Non-labor Income 0.014 0.005 (0.007)“ (0.007) Statistics for Joint Test of Instrumental VariablesChi2(2) 4.89 5.2 Prob>chi2 0.0867 0.0744 1.Standard errors are in parenthesis. “significant at 5% level;* significant at 10% level. 2. Other variables included in the regressions are the year and year/ region dummies 127 Chapter 3 Estimation With or Without Strict Exogeneity Assumption in Unequally Spaced Panel Data 3.1 Introduction In unequally spaced panel data, observations are missing entirely in certain periods and they are only available on non-consecutive basis.1 Unequally spaced panel data are normal rather than exceptions in many surveys carried out in developing countries where the survey was interrupted because of funding issues or other reasons. Mckenzie (2001) documented some examples of unequally spaced surveys in developing countries. There are two other well-known surveys which we would add to this list: Indonesia Family Life Survey (IF LS), whose 1 Different from unequally spaced panel data, unbalanced panel data, according to Arellano and Bond (1991), is a sample in which consecutive observations on individual units are available, but the number of time periods available may vary from unit to unit as well as the historical points to which the observations correspond. 128 survey periods are 1993, 1997 and 2000; and Russian Longitudinal Monitory Survey (RLMS), whose survey periods are 1992, 1993, 1994, 1995,1996,1998,2000, 2001, 2002. For unbalanced panel data, Arellano and Bond (1991) noted that nothing fundamental changes in the econometric methods, provided a minimal number of continuous time periods are available for each unit. Wooldridge (2002, Chapter 17) also remarks that, provided the decision to select units out of a panel is made randomly, any differencing method on any subset of the observed panel is consistent and the usual test statistics are valid. For the unevenly spaced panel, all observations are non-consecutive because in certain periods, the entire cross-section may not be observed. Such a pattern of data missing would cause complications when current outcome of certain variable depends on the lagged values of the variable itself or the lagged values of other variables. Baltagi and Wu (1999) considered the case in panel data where the disturbances following a stationary AR(1). They develop a feasible generalized least squares (GLS) procedure that takes into account that under the normal procedure, the transformed disturbances are still heteroskedastic in the unequally spaced data. Mckenzie (2001) studies AR(1) models with an unequally spaced pseudo-panel. In this case, the differencing approach can no longer be directly applied and, furthermore, unequal spacing in a dynamic model imposes nonlinear restrictions on the parameters. In the pseudo-panel case, the population is divided into 129 certain cohorts and the mean of the cohorts is taken over the individual in each cohorts. The resulting data is a pseudo—panel over the cohorts. And non-linear least squares, minimum distance, and one-step estimators are used to estimate the parameters. In genuine panel data, averaging can be taken over the entire sample, but the estimates of the parameters can only be based on small observations in the averaged model. This paper focuses on a dynamic model, where the outcome of the dependent variable depends on both the current value and the lagged value of the explanatory variables. Section 2 considers a model with a strict exogeneity assumption. A classic minimum distance estimation method and an one-step GMM method are proposed for the consistent estimates of the parameters. The two-step GMM method is also discussed. In section 3, the same model is studied without strict exogeneity assumption. Arellano and Bond (1991) method is used to account for the violation of strict exogeneity. The classic minimum distance estimation then follows to recover the structural parameters. It also shows that the same one—step GMM method also applies. Section 4 concludes the paper. 130 3.2 Estimation Under Strict Exogeneity Condition 3.2.1 Static Model Consider the following panel data regression model: y” :xiifi'l'ci'l‘l‘id (i=1,...,N;t=1,2,...,T) (3.1) , where mm is a 1 x k-vector of explanatory variables, ,8 is a k x 1-vector of parameters to be estimated; c,-, the time-invariant unobservables of unit i are allowed to be arbitrarily correlated with l‘z‘t; flit is an idiosyncratic disturbance. The strict exogeneity assumption is : E(#z‘,t|$z', 0:) = 0 (3-2) So far, the model setup is a standard basic fixed effect model. When all the observations are missing for certain periods, as in the unequally spaced panel, this model becomes a special case of unbalanced panel covered by Wooldridge (2002). Following his notation, the selection indicators (Sit) in the unevenly spaced panel certainly depend only on exogenous rules, so the assumption “Malawi, 32') = 0 (3-3) 131 is satisfied. In this case, the selection indicators are the same for all observations and they are all zero in certain periods, thus we can omit the subscript t in the indicator, that is: st = 0 for some t’s. Assume that all the observations are not missing in the first period (t=1) and the last possible period (t=T). Then the number of time periods observed for all observations should satisfy: T,- Z 2, where T,- = Esit. Fixed effect estimation can be extended easily to the unevenly spaced panel and the FE estimator is consistent under strict exogeneity assumption in equation (3). Furthermore under homoskedasticity and serial independence assumption for the error term, the normal inference also holds, as shown in Wooldridge (2002, Section 17.2). 3.2.2 Dynamic Model with Lagged Explanatory Variables Now assume a dynamic model with lagged explanatory variables: yiat = $i¢fi + 11545-10 + Ci + ”Lt (2:1, ..., N,t=1,...,T) (3.4) where 50,3, is a 1 x k vector of explanatory variables that are dated contemporaneously with the dependent variable gm; w,,t_1 is a scalar, which is dated one-period lag of the dependent variable. 132 The strict exogeneity assumption in this model is: E(Hitl$iawia Ci) = 0 (3-5) This assumption is the key assumption for the estimation method we propose in this section. So far the model is standard. In the unevenly spaced panel, we need some notation to specify the pattern of missing data. Let us denote the observed time periods by t3, where s = 1,2, ...,r and r g T. That is, y,,ts,x,,ts,wi,ts are observed. Then the model specified in equation(3.4), in the unevenly spaced panel case, should be: this = witsfl + wits—10‘ + C: + Mtg (i=1,-~.N,8 = .-- T) (3-6) The 7' — 1 equations in this model can be written as: 312' = $15 + ”wt—101 + CijT + M (i = 1, N) (3-7) ,where jT is a (r — 1) x 1 vector of ones. In this dynamic model, w“ s_1 may not be observed. The closest observed period to the (ts — 1)“ period is period (ts_1). We can use the value in the closest period to predict w” 8_1. The assumption we make about the data generating process of wig is that the linea projector, L(w,,t3|wi,ts_m), is stationary for m 2 1. That is, we assume: wl,ts : me’i,t3 -m + Vits (3‘8) 133 for m = 1, 2, This assumption does not put restrictions on the coefficient of the lagged dependent variable if the lag length is different, and it only assumes the coefficient to be the same for the same lag length. By definition of a linear projection, the error term 11,18 has the following properties: Ems) = 0 (3-9) COU(1Ui,t3—ma VitS) = 0 (3.10) At the same time, since 3321 does not help predict w” for all t, we also have the following property of Vits Cov(u,'ts,x,;) = 0 (3.11) Based on the model specified in equation (3.8), we can predict 101-$3-1 by the following equation: w,,t8_1= ”(ts—1)‘(ts_1)wts—1+ ”its—1 (i=1, 2, ..., N; S =1,2,..., T) (3.12) Substitute equation (3.12) into equation (3.6), we can write: yi,t3 = $i,t3fi + wt3_17r(t3—1)-(ts_1)a + Ci + ”its + Quilts—1) (3-13) If t, — 1 = t3_1, then (3.13) reduced to a standard model in an equally spaced data. In vector form, let h be the number of distinct lag length between period (t3_1) and period (ts — 1), where (h > 1). And also denote the magnitude of the 134 gap by mj with m = (ts — 1) — (ts_1) ,j =1,...,h. Then T — 1 equation in (3.13) can be written as: where w,,_1 = (wiy2_1,w,,t3_1, ...,w,,tT_1)' is a (r — 1) x 1 vector of the lagged explanatory variables that we want to predict; II = f (7r) = (7r,n1,7rm2, ..., nmh)’ is a h x 1 vector of parameters in predicting w,,_1. And wz_1 is a (r — 1) x h matrix, where the non-zero element w,- t1,w,- t2: ..., w,- t is located in column s 9 a 7"]. mj; mj is the gap in time period between the element in wit-1 and the corresponding element in w,’_1. Lastly, e, = u,- + oil/,- is a (r — 1) x 1 vector of is error terms. Now the error term will consist of an extra term if w,,ts_1 estimated from wi,t3— 1. For example, if t1 = 1; t2 = 3; t3 = 6; t4 = 7; t5 = 9, the estimation equation in (3.14) will be: yi,3 132's 0 ’wz',1 0 1 Ms + 0521.2 yrs 332'6 fl 0 0 w2:3 . M6+a€z°5 9 = a + a “-1 a + . + a ’ yi,7 1171.7 was 0 0 7,2 6’37 um 31239 331,9 0 101.7 0 #239 + 05i,8 The first method we consider to estimate ,8 and a is the classic minimum distance (CMD) estimator. Letting z, = (33,-, 711:4) be a (r — 1) x (k + h) matrix of exogenous variables, and 6 = (fi’, 7')’ be (k + h) x 1 vector of parameters to be estimated, where 7 = Ha. The model in (3.14) can then be expressed as: y,- =zi6+cij7+ei (i=1,...,N) (3.15) 135 Under strict exogeneity assumptions in (3.5) and the conditional mean assumptions in (3.10) and (3.11), together with usual rank conditions, the fixed effect estimator for (3.15) is consistent. We call this fixed effect estimator éFE- And 6‘“; = (2,2,82;,,82,,,S)-1(2,2,szggtsym) , where the double dots stands for demeaned form of variables. Without further assumptions on the serial correlation in the error term, the demeaned form of error term «'5', might be serially correlated and heteroskedastic. Thus the robust variance matrix estimator should be applied for any statistical inferences. The estimated robust variance matrix of the fixed effect estimator for this model is: 5‘2 = AWE”) = (Z Elia—WE 2:204 (3.16) where, V = Z,- jig-g2,- and 2; is the error term from fixed effect estimation, that is, e,- = y,- — 2,8 F E. This variance matrix is valid in the presence of any heteroskedasticity or serial correlation, provided that r is small relative to N (Wooldridge 2002). The fixed effect estimator S F E is a (k + h) x 1 vector of estimated coefficients in the “reduced ”form. We denote the “structural ”form of coefficients to be a (k + 1) x 1 vector: 60 = (B’, a). To denote that the “reduced ”form of coefficients 0 = (B’,rrm1a,...,7rmha)' is a non-linear function of 60, we write 0 = f(60), f : Rk+1 —+ Rk+h is a continuously differentiable function. Since éFE is a 136 consistent estimator of 6, we can recover the estimates of the 60 from éFE- The classical minimum distance estimator of 60, denoted by 60 M D is the solution to the problem: MinaoléFE - f(9o)l’f?_1léFE — f (90)] (3-17) ,where {2‘1 is given in (3.16). The solution do M D solves the first order condition: [Vsof(éCArD)l'9'lléFE - “germ” = 0 (3-18) ,where Vgof(SCMD) is a (k + h) x (k + 1) Jacobian of f(éCMD)- Hansen (1982) establishes that the resulting estimator 90 M D is consistent and asymptotically normal. The estimated variance of SC M D takes the form: A AvafléCMD) = N —1{lV00f (genroll'fl-l [Vaof (écarolll (3-19) The second method we consider is joint estimation of 7r, B, a through generalized method of moment. This is an application of GMM framework for sequential estimation studied by Newey and McFadden (1994). In this application, the feasible estimation of B and (1 depends on the estimation of 7r in the first place. By applying the general GMM formula to simultaneously estimate the two sets of parameters, we can get consistent standard error estimators for the estimation of B and a. 137 The first set of moment conditions does not include parameter B and a. It only involves using observed period in the estimation of 7r. For example, the following regression contains 7r1 and M in previous example: wi,3 0 10231 W1 52,3 10137 = 101-"6 0 [ “2 J + 81,7 10239 0 101,7 51,9 In general, we write w,- = 105:1“ + E, (3.20) The dimension of w, is l x 1 where l 2 h; and luff—1 is a l X h matrix of observed values of w as well. In other words, the dimension of w,- and wail depend on the lag length in observed data as well as the missing period. In order to be able to use the estimators from the observed period, the lag length between observed periods must include the lag length needed to estimate the missing period. The number of moment conditions depends on the lag length of observed periods as well as the lag length needed to estimate the missing period. We use f1(w, 7r) to denote the first set of moment conditions which involves parameter 7r only: f1(w. H) = Elw“2,-1(w. — wailnn = 0 (3.21) The second set of moment condition, denoted by f2(w, x, B, a, II), is specified in the differenced form of (3.14), where the unobserved time-invariant heterogeneity is differenced out. This set of moment conditions involve the estimation of B, a as 138 well as IT: f2(w,a:, H,fi,a) = E [ wjf ] [Ayi — (Asa-B — Aw,”_ll‘la)] 1' 0 (3.22) 1 . Define the sample version of f1 and f2 by f1 and f2, where —Zw**’ ,- _1(w --— wfiln) = 0 (3.23) N I f2(w3x1H,/Baa)=I—1V-Z [ mil/:1. 1 :l [AZ/i — (Altifi "" sz_1Hoz)] = 0 (3.24) The moment conditions for simultaneous estimation of H, B, a are f(w. x. H, a a) = {fun}. H)’. f2(w. x. H. a a)’]’ (3.25) The GMM estimate of the parameters thus is the solution to the following minimum criteria: min(f)'W(f)’ (3.26) and the optimal weighting matrix W = @[flm 1:, II, B, (1)]. Further, let 6 = (B'a)' and call the GMM estimates of 9 and II, 6 and f1. Define A the sample Jacobian terms by F11 = an1(w,fl);1"21= an2(w, FLO) and [‘22 = ng2(w,$, 110) and ‘II = —f’1_11f1. In our application, 1 I‘11 = _TV_ Z(w{*_1'wf*_1) (3.27) 139 ’A r2,:_ 1 “EN: (11:? [1051) (3.28) 0221:1111 lAu’i,—l) and 1‘22 2 _i ZiNzl($i,A$l) Zi="(1($ilAw:-1H)A (3 29) 25:1(u’Z—1'A13z‘) Zi=1< u’i,—1’Awi,—1H) The variance of 6 is given by Newey and McFadden (1994) as the following: A Var(6)=(-1F22 ZIH N {2] (f2+1“21\11> (f2+F21‘1’)’(l} Fee (3.30) It is worth mentioning the alternative of estimating the parameters through a two-step GMM estimation. The first step is to estimate 11 by the moment conditions given in (3.21). The second step is to estimate B and a by the moment conditions given in (3.22), taking H from the first step as given. Newy and McFadden (1994) derives the condition, under which the standard error of the estimates of B and a is not affected by the estimation of II from (3.21) only. The condition is F21 = 0. In our application, it means that if and only if a = 0, does the first step have no effect on the second-step asymptotic variance. In empirical application, when the null hypothesis that a = 0 can not be rejected from the two step estimation, the standard error from the second step need not 140 be corrected. In other cases when a 76 0, the one-step GMM estimation outlined above is no less efficient than the two-step GMM and the standard error is correct. One concern in terms of the computation of the one-step GMM is that the iteration may not converge since the moment conditions are not linear in parameters. This may be alleviated by using the two-step estimates as the initial value in the iteration. 3.3 Estimation Without Strict Exogeneity Condition 3.3.1 Static Model We are still look at the following model in the unevenly spaced panel: yi,t3 = $i,t,sfi + a; + mi, (331) but the assumption we make on the error term “Lts is the following: E(Hi,t3l$i,ts—1’xi,t3—2a -°-»$z',1aci) = 0 (3.32) By this assumption, “its is uncorrelated with error terms pm]. for t; < tj, conditional on time invariant heterogeneity. In other words, “is is predetermined. So, the correlation of the error terms with contemporaneous and future values of the explanatory variables is allowed. One example would be the regression of working hours on wage arrears shock, when working hours affect the possibility of wage arrears shocks in the subsequent period. 141 The general method used for the model with violation of strict exogeneity assumption also applies in the unevenly spaced panel. First difference the data in the unevenly spaced panel gives us: 31mg — yi,t3_1 = (30mg — $i,t3_1)fl + (Hats - Mi,ts_1) (3-33) and the observed level or change in the lagged value of arms can be used as instrument variables. That is, $i.ts_2v$i,ts_3v--:Or (332'.ts_2 -— $i,ts,3), (“$3-3 — x,,ts_4)...can be used as instrument variables for (sums — mists-1) in a GLS estimation. Or in the Arellano and Bond (1992) framework, more of the instruments can be explored in the GMM estimation. 3.3.2 Dynamic Model Consider the following model: yi,ts = $i,ts(3+wz',ts—1Q+Cz' +#z',ts (i=1,---,N,8 =1,---,T) (334) We assume that conditional on individual time invariant heterogeneity, explanatory variables 3:, and w,- are predetermined with respect to the error term: E(#it|$i,ts—1,$z',ts-2, 502,1; wi,t3—1awi,ts—2a ..., 101,1; Ci) = 0 (3-35) The within estimator for (3.34) is inconsistent because the within transformed error is a function of predetermined information and thus is not orthogonal to the within transformed explanatory variables. A common econometric approach for 142 handling violation of strict exogeneity is to first differencing this equation and apply instrument variables on the differenced equation. The differenced equation can be written as: Ail/ms = Al‘msb’ + Aims—101 + Aims (335) ,where A denotes the first difference operation. That is, Ayms = yi,ts — yi,ts_1§ Axus = 13mg - 33i,t3_1; Awi,t3—1 = was-1 — “Jets—2 and Alias = flats — Hi.ts_1- As we mentioned before, mm 3-1 may not be observed in the unevenly spaced panel and the most recent recent period that is observed is period t3_1. Based on the assumptions of (3.8) and (3.10) for 10, we can predict wi,t s_1 by using observed period. But we need to be careful in the prediction when ”wit is not strict exogenous with respect to the error term. For example, when t3_1 = t3 — 1, that is the previous one period is the most recent period observed for some 3, the fact that E(w1,ts_1#i,ts_1) # 0 will cause the predicted term to be correlated with the error term. In this case, we need to use one lag period before the most recent period, that is "Luz-$84, to predict wi,t—1- But if all the gap between two periods are greater than one, then we can still use the most recent period to predict the missing period. To simply the notation, we assume that the gap between two observed period is greater than one, thus we can use the most recent period as predictor. The first differenced form of the model in terms of observed 143 period can be written as: yi.t3 - yi.t3_1 = (36mg - $i.ts_1)fi + iwz’,t8_17r(tS—1)—(t3_1) (3-37) —wzf,t3_277(ts_2)_(ts_2)la + (Hus — Hi,t3_1) +(Vi,t3—1 — Vi.ts—2)0 In matrix form, (3.37) can be written as: Ayz- = Ari-[1’ + Awilfla + A6.) (3.38) where, A6,- = Au,- + aAui. There are two issues that need to be addressed. One is that the correlation between Arms and Anus is nonzero, because E(AIi,t3A/1ni.ts) = E($i,t3 — Ii,t3_1)(#i,ts — #i,ts_1) = E($i,tsllz',t3) — E($1,t5#~i,t3_1) -+- E($i,ts_1#i,ts_1)- All these three terms are not equal to zero, according to the assumption that x,- are predetermined. Another issue is that the parameter Ha is nonlinear and we want to “recover ”the “structural ”coefficient oz. The first issue can be addressed easily by instrument variable estimation. The possible instruments for Amati; are [Hiya/“Lt? Marl-$34]. For example, starting from period t3,in the Arellano and Bond (1991) framework, the matrix of 144 instruments, denoted by Z,- is : i$i,t1a(wi,t2 -— wi.t1)l 0 Z1 = ' 0 [13211 a 113m? ---33i,t1._2, (wi,t.,_1 — 10:39-2” The estimated weighting matrix is: = 2,2,f(&,)(&,)'z, (3.39) A5,: is residuals from the preliminary consistent estimator, such as 2SLS using a couple of lags as instrument variables. The consistent estimator, denoted by OGMM = ((BIGAIM’ HOGAIAI)’, is: éGMM = [(131723 Aw:1),Zi(i>,er(A$iaAW:1)l-1l(A$iaAw:1)’Zi(i)’ZiA3/il (3.40) A consistent estimate of the asymptotic variance of 66 M M is given by: O = Avar(6GMM) = [(Ax,, Awil)'Z,-’Z£(A:ri, Aw:1)]-1 (3.41) To recover the parameter 60 = (13’, a) from 63 M M, we can apply the classic minimum distance estimator in (3.17) and (3.18)to obtain consistent estimator of 60. The one-step GMM method proposed in section 2 can also be applied in this case. The only difference is that the set of moment conditions in (3.22) will be in the following form: I 132/T21. ] [Ag/2' - (A3316 — AwZ_1Ha)] = 0 (3.42) w 2,—1 f2,(w,2:,l'l,fi,a) = E [ 145 Starting from t3, i$i,t1ia 0 l$i,t ,332',t a] JUL-2: 1. 2 0 [x.,.,,x.,.,,...x.,.._21 Thus 6, a as well as II can be estimated through: 600,23, [1.5.60 = [fi(w,H)’, fi'(w,x,H,fi,a)'l' (3-43) The one-step GMM method is no more complicated in the case without strict exogeneity than the case with strict exogeneity. The only difference is there will be fewer possible moment conditions in the second set of moments containing the parameters 6 and a. The variance of the estimates of 6 and a given in (3.30) also applies. 3.4 Conclusion Estimation in unevenly spaced panel in a static model does not involve more complication. In a dynamic model, the estimation involves predicting the missing lagged value. In this paper, we consider a model with one lagged explanatory variable. The classic minimum distance estimation can be applied to recover the structural parameters from the consistent estimator of the reduced form parameters. The consistent estimator for the reduced form parameters can be 146 obtained from either fixed effect estimation or GMM estimation, depending on the assumption about the exogeneity of the explanatory variables with respect to the error term. Also, the one-step GMM method can be applied in both cases. 147 BIBLIOGRAPHY Angrist, J. D., and W. K. Newey (1991),“Over-Identification Test in Earnings Functions With Fixed Effects, ”Journal of Business 85 Economic Statistics Vol. 9, No.3: 317-323. Arellano, M. and S. R. Bond (1991), “Some Specification Tests for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, ” Review of Economic Studies 58: 277-298. Baltagi, B. H., and Y. Change (1994),“Incomplete Panels—A comparative study of alternative estimators for the unbalanced one—way error component regression model, ”Journal of Econometrics 62: 67-89. Baltagi, B. H., and P. X. Wu (1999),“Unequally Spaced Panel Data Regressions with AR(l) Disturbances, ”Econometric Theory, 15: 814-823. Baltagi, B. H. (2001), Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, John Wiley & Sons, LTD. Mckenzie, D. J .(2001), “Estimation of AR(l) Models with Unequally Spaced Pseudo-panels, ”Econometrics Journal Vol 4: 89—108. Newey, W., and D. McFadden (1994), “Large Sample Estimation and Hypothesis Testing, ”in Handbook of Econometrics Vol. IV, ed. R. Engle and D. McFadden: 2113-2241. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, MIT press: Cambridge, MA. 148 m 9 , . mi18 H . , . . . will)” , . nifllel.4 . . . U‘ilo . . . E . T . . . ul.3 , 5'19 . . “H2 , 1 . . Gi 111 . mil. . , .. - ml3 . . .