J» - wt;- r" Jzncv .‘. ‘ .23: rife» u..- ESQ. ifia‘ifiu a 0.. ' ' ' go'- ,. .. .A. v if? :4? #1:... .... :21» o i Jon if; ~>~i~ r», P .i’ . :" Ami»: .. 5: " A. 5“?- 33.2.; hf“ lm Ari/24 5493;? (9 7 5 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled ESSAYS ON ARBITRAGE ACTIVITIES presented by Umit Gurkan Gurun has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Ph.D. degree in Finance Pro ssors Signatdre 10 ”a? 0700:7/ Date MSU is an Afi‘innative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution r «or; w W — v -— ~—.—.——<—-—~—'—‘r—v fl ‘— LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINE return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 cJCIRC/DateDuo.p65«p.15 ESSAYS ON ARBITRAGE ACTIVITIES By Umit Gurkan Gurun A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Finance 2004 This study 0 visibility hyp should attram low substitut their prices d may signal ti Where short Visible" “he “31" Can €Xpl; Mi“gelgrin (2 In the SECOnd ABSTRACT ESSAYS ON ARBITRAGE ACTIVITIES By Umit Gurkan Gurun This study contains two chapters. In the first chapter, we provide new insights to the visibility hypothesis of Miller (1977), who argues that increased attention to a given stock should attract and convince more investors to buy the stock. We argue that stocks with low substitutability risk are more likely to experience abnormal trading activity when their prices deviate from fundamentals and postulate that the abnormal trading activities may signal the intentions of the traders, presumably arbitrageurs. Thus, in an economy where short selling is restricted, stocks with close substitutes are more likely to be “visible” when they are underpriced. We present empirical evidence that substitutability risk can explain the high-volume return premium documented by Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001). In the second chapter, we show that cross sectional differences of momentum profits across 31 countries can be explained by market intelligence measures such as investor sophistication and earnings management severeness. We present three novel findings: First, momentum is more pronounced in countries that have severe earnings management practices, suggesting that momentum is not due to market under reaction due to earnings related information. Second, momentum strategies appear to be profitable in countries that have more sophisticated investors. And third, the growth rate of momentum strateg)"S VOL suggesting thiz investors. OVL’ risk is the pric and Zhou (2i? trading costs. strategy’s volatility (exploitability risk) is positively related to investor sophistication, suggesting that momentum strategies are riskier in markets dominated by sophisticated investors. Overall our empirical evidence is consistent with the notion that exploitability risk is the price of momentum profits, and complements the findings of Lesmond, Schill, and Zhou (2004), who show that stocks that generate momentum profits have higher trading costs. To my uncle Nevzat Kip (1944-2000) iv lam Salem I professor 6- I queSlIOIISs Ihi comminee m" Schroder for acknowledge 3 Finance DEPL‘A‘ ideas. Profess helped me de\ I feel extreme during my dm Altsu for prm' can eXpress r Dalgin, Dagh Oguzhan Ku encouragemer Lew but not Sema Gurun . ml heme. I a] home in US. had courage 1 IOI her infirm- ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I am grateful for the excellent guidance and support of my committee chair and mentor, Professor G. Geoffrey Booth. Without his insightful comments and thought provoking questions, this dissertation would not be completed. I would also like to thank my committee members, Professor Richard Baillie, Kirt Butler, Charlie Hadlock and Mark Schroder for their help and continued support throughout my studies. I would like to acknowledge many fruitful discussions with other faculty and fellow doctoral students of Finance Department at MSU. They provided an excellent environment for nurturing new ideas. Professor Gautam Kaul, Tamer Cavusgil, and Mitchell Warachka’s comments helped me develop my ideas. I feel extremely fortunate to have received support from many other people before and during my doctoral studies. My primary debts are to Professor Veday Akgiray and Celal Aksu for providing me an opportunity to study finance. There are no words with which I can express my deepest appreciation to my friends and mentors Salim Buge, Burak Dalgin, Daghan Erbakan, Omer Erdem, Emre Gurkan, Mustafa Kamasak, Ali Koo, Oguzhan Kulekci, Volkan Muslu, and Bulent Yildirim for their support and encouragement. Least but not last, I thank my family - Ayse Gurun, Muzaffer Gurun, Jale Gurun, and Sema Gurun - for their incredible patience and continued support while I was away from my home. I also thank Elizabeth Booth, Mike Booth, and Matt Booth for making me feel home in US. Without my farmly in Turkey and US. standing behind, I would not have had courage to write this dissertation. Finally, I am indebted to my fiancee Ayfer Seyfi for her inspiration, patience and unqualified love that kept me emotionally alive. w I llST OF TAB LIST OF FIGI. INTRODL'CT‘. l. Does 1“ Return lntrodu The Lit Limite | Trading The .\lk Genera Assets Inx'estr: Constr. SOlUtic Empin' Empiri Dania POnfi) TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES LIST OF FIGURES INTRODUCTION 1. 1.1 1.2 1.2.1 1.2.2 1.3 1.3.1 1.3.2 1.3.3 1.3.4 1.3.5 1.3.6 1.4 1.4.1 1.4.2 1.4.3 1.4.4 Does Fundamental Risk of Arbitrage Explain the High-Volume Return Premium? Introduction The Literature Limited Arbitrage Trading Volume Literature The Model General Setup Assets Investors and Their Investment Opportunity Sets Constraints of the Arbitrageur Solution of the Arbitrageur’s Problem Empirical Implications of the Solutions Empirical Tests Data and Methodology Portfolio Formation and Returns Measure of Substitutability Risk Measure of Divergence of Opinions vi viii xii 10 10 10 ll 13 15 22 24 24 26 28 29 1.4.6 1.4.7 1.4.8 1.6 APPENDIX 1 .\1ea. 1, investors i (i=A,B) receive an endowment that is correlated with the asset payoff (5,). We assume that the endowment of investors A (B) in period t is lit-15: Fur-15)- The coefficient UH measures the extent to which the endowment covaries with 5b When u,-, is high, the covariance is high, and thus the willingness of investor i to hold asset i in period t—l is low. We refer to u,_] as the “supply shock” of investor i in period t—l to emphasize that it negatively affects investor demand in that period.’2 For the base case, the supply shock u, is deterministic and identical in all periods, that is, u, = uo for t= 0, 1, .. ,T—l. All uncertainty is resolved in period 1. For example, shocks can be interpreted as correlated noise trades caused by herding that lead to deviations from the fundamental price temporarily. Due to different supply shocks, investors A and B will have different propensities to hold the assets. Since they cannot trade with each other because of the segmented market, only the arbitrageur can exploit the price wedge created by these shocks. Intuitively, if the arbitrageur has infinite wealth, she will be able to absorb shocks in all periods and make risk free profit by longing asset A and shorting asset B. The critical implication of the opposite supply shock assumption for the model is that investors A and B incur different shocks. The arbitrageur does not have any endowment, ’2 To be consistent with the zero net supply assumption, the endowments can be interpreted as positions in a different but correlated asset. This specification of endowments is quite standard in the literature (Gromb and Vayanos (2002), O’Hara (1995)). As shown in Gromb and Vayanos (2002), the assumption of equal shocks is for simplicity and do not change the conclusions. 12 ‘r 41".“ so she is no shocks to (11 words, She circumstanc The merits \ receives a r shock. The Willing to St buy. Throui provides liq 1.3.4 Con The arbitra; The margir In the me1 the im'estn investors a: long mm arbitraSEUr occur in th of the mar i . n a gIVEU so she is not affected by the supply shock directly. However, the difference of the supply shocks to different segments of the market provides her an indirect endowment. In other words, she exploits price discrepancies between assets A and B, which arise from the circumstances described above. One can think of arbitrageur as a go-between. The merits of this model can best be understood by an example. Suppose that investor A receives a positive supply shock (u0>0), in which case investor B receives a negative shock. The arbitrageur buys asset A (underpriced asset) from the investor A, who is willing to sell, and sells asset B (overpriced asset) to the investor B, who is willing to buy. Through this transaction the arbitrageur makes a profit and at the same time provides liquidity to the other investors. 1.3.4 Constraints of the Arbitrageur The arbitrageur is subject to not only a budget constraint but also a margin constraint. The margin accounts can be thought of as collateral to insure possible losses. Collateral in the form of long positions in other assets are risky positions and may create losses for the investment house who acts as custodian for the arbitrageur. Therefore, in practice, investors are often required to keep a cash amount in their margin accounts rather than a long position in another asset. It is assumed that the margin constraint requires arbitrageur to have enough cash (not other stocks) to cover the maximum loss that can occur in the margin account. This implies that her ability to invest is limited by the value of the margin account. In particular, she may be unable to eliminate a price discrepancy in a given period, even if she knows that the discrepancy will disappear in the next 13 period. L811" without a m L61 XL! (1611 margin acco I1.1+l The requiret ._/ _ ill—IA! Where \1'[ dc - - | negativity c( default. Not} later, we “'1 Fina”): the 2 Max x4 [9x "-91 T- to 14] t 1 period. Later, we will relax this assumption and solve the arbitrageur’s problem with and without a margin constraint for perfectly and imperfectly substitutable assets. Let Xi“ denote the number of shares in asset i in period t, and let Vit be the value of the margin account for asset i. We have Vi,1+1 : Vi,t + xi,t (pi,t+l — pi,t),1=A,B. The requirement that Vim Z 0 implies that W: : VA! + VBt Z maX(xA,z(pA,z _ pA,t+l ))+max(x8,t(p8,t ‘p3,1+1)) pA,r+l p8,t+l where w denotes the arbitrageur’s wealth in period t. In other words, imposing the non- negativity constraint on the sum of each margin account ensures that arbitrageurs never default. Notice that the margin constraint is symmetric for both long and short positions. Later, we will change this assumption and completely restrict short sales in certain cases. Finally, the arbitrageur’s problem becomes: Max E0U(WT) x x A,t ’ B,t t=..0 ,1 T-1 subject to the dynamic wealth constraint, wr+l : W, + Z xi,t(pi,t+l _pi,t) f0? t : Oala°°9T_1 i=A,B and the margin constraint, l4 Wt 2 2 max (xi,t (17),, —pi,t+l)), i=A,B P1,:+1 1.3.5 Solution of the Arbitrageur’s Problem In this section, the arbitrageur’s demand is characterized under different assumptions. Specifically, we focus on four situations: (1) no margin constraints and perfectly substitutable assets, (2) margin constraints and perfectly substitutable assets, (3) no margin constraints and imperfect substitutes, and (4) margin constraints and imperfect substitutes. The general equilibrium solution for investors A and B and the arbitrageur’s portfolio selection problem for perfect substitutes is provided in Gromb and Vayanos (2002). Our interest lies in the relationship between arbitrageurs demand and assets substitutability, therefore we briefly summarize their main results for perfect substitutes and then focus on how substitutability affects the arbitrageur’s demand. Case I: No margin constraints and perfect substitutes Gromb and Vayanos (2002) show that, in equilibrium, due to the symmetry of the set up and perfect substitution, opposite supply shocks will induce opposite risk premiums: (¢A,t _ ¢A,t+l) = _(¢B,t _ ¢B,r+1) : (¢t — ¢t+1), the arbitrageur will buy Xt shares of asset A and sell Xt shares of asset B to satisfy the zero net supply assumption (market clearance). Therefore, in the absence of margin constraint, the arbitrageur’s wealth constraint reduces to 15 .‘ 2 II, I'I‘HJ I That is, the substitutes ' amounts in '. ofthe arbitr; place in the Case II: Ma If assets at arbitrageur f not bear an). that II” +1 2 ‘17 wt+l = wt +xr(¢r _ ¢r+l +5r+1) —xt(—¢t +¢r+l +61+1), wt+l = Wt + 2xr(¢t - ¢t+1) That is, the wealth increase does not involve any risk because the assets are perfect substitutes to each other. The arbitrageur absorbs all the shocks and invests infinite amounts in asset A and B as long as the price wedge is positive. In equilibrium, existence of the arbitrageur keeps prices at their fundamental levels at all times, and no trading take place in the market unless there is mispricing in either assets. Case II: Margin constraints and perfect substitutes If assets are perfectly substitutable, the zero net supply assumption ensures that arbitrageur holds opposite positions in the two risky assets (x, = x Ar = —xB,) and does not bear any risk. Similar to the previous case, the arbitrageur’s wealth constraint implies that Wt+1 : Wt +2xr(¢t —¢r+1), Furthermore, the margin constraint of the arbitrageur implies that Wt 2 max(x, (—¢t + ¢r+l — 51+1))+ rrsiax(—x, (¢t _ ¢r+l _ 61+1)) 6H1 1+1 => w. 2 231391 + max(x.(—¢, + ¢...>)+ max(— x.(¢. — an) 16 U '4". l/\ [\L that is, the asset payof: all uncertair to the arbitr. In other \v. arbitrageur constraint. It If the uncert Shoe that th 0n the arbitr; the PTOfitab COml‘varable ' Lonssmff (:1 larger) and “I \\hen 'rl : ‘l wt :>x is — 26 —2 (¢1_¢r+l), that is, the margin constraint reduces arbitrageurs ability to exploit opportunities when asset payoffs are more volatile and the arbitrageur has less wealth. Since we assume that all uncertainty is resolved at time 1, the value of the price wedge,(¢t — ¢r+1)’ is known to the arbitrageur. As long as (Q -— ¢t +1) > 0, she invests up to the financial constraint. In other words, if the prices are known to converge to each other over time, the arbitrageur uses all her resources to exploit this opportunity. Due to the margin constraint, however, the price wedge does not converge to 0 at all periods as in Case I. If the uncertainty is resolved over time rather than at time 1, Gromb and Vayanos (2002) show that the arbitrageur’s demand for risky assets depends not only on expected return on the arbitrage opportunity but also the covariance between the arbitrageur’s wealth and the profitability of investment opportunities. The interpretation of their result is comparable to the findings of Shleifer and Vishny (1997), Xiong (2001), and Liu and Longstaff (2003)’s findings under different setups: Due to the uncertainty of shocks, the arbitrageur may lose some wealth if the price wedge increases (mispricing becomes larger) and this reduction in wealth prevents her from exploiting more valuable arbitrage opportunities. W When x, = — I 25 —2 (¢1_¢r+l) is used in the wealth constraint, we get 17 .~ :: W u1+1 I of price we invests more Case III: N Assume that the price vs 3.58.61 \VIII bc‘ llllCS‘lOr :\ \\ but they “‘11 invests in constraint rec Ivtfl 2 11 that 15’ She is Strategy. In emCiem Prit considered It L‘nder thesg OptileatiQn 5 Wm = W that is, the profit of arbitrageur depends on the evolution '6_-(¢. —¢,.1>’ of price wedge. As it decreases over time, the arbitrageur’s wealth increases, and she invests more in the next period. Case 111: No margin constraints and imperfect substitutes Assume that asset A does not have a perfect substitute. If a positive shock hits investor A, the price wedge between the new price and the efficient price will become ¢, , and the asset will be underpriced by ¢, . In the absence of a perfect substitute, the arbitrageur and investor A will have the same investment opportunity set (asset A and the risk-free asset) but they will have different expectations about the value of asset A. The arbitrageur invests in A by using risk-free asset as the other leg of the arbitrage. Her wealth constraint reduces to Wt+1 : wt +xt(¢t _¢t+l + 5H1), that is, she is subject to the volatility of asset A’s payoff. The payoff volatility represents the fundamental (substitutability) risk involved in this strategy. In the certainty case, the arbitrageur knows that the price will converge to its efficient price at time T, but due to uncovered fimdamental arbitrage risk, she can be considered to be a speculator as opposed to an arbitrageur. Under these assumptions, the arbitrageur’s problem reduces to a mean-variance Optimization problem, and the demand of the arbitrageur becomes 18 a: it al 1 Notice that decreases. I strategy inv risky. so the the substitu variability oi On the one 1 “I“ be deter Uncertainty 1 the arbitrag. x ___ (¢t — ¢r+l) ‘ a Var(6)' Notice that as arbitrageur’s risk aversion (or) increases, the demand for the risky asset decreases. Risk aversion was irrelevant in the previous cases because the arbitrage strategy involved no risk. However, imperfect substitutes cause that strategy to become risky, so the solution incorporates this effect. The arbitrageur is compensated for taking the substitutability risk by the expected return, (¢, —¢,+l). Not surprisingly, the variability of cash flows reduces the demand, as it does in case 11. On the one hand, if the uncertainty is resolved in period 1, the return from this strategy will be deterministic and equal to the numerator (€15, — (4,”) . On the other hand, if the uncertainty of supply shocks is resolved gradually, further return uncertainty is added to the arbitrageur’s strategy and show up in the numerator of the demand expression as (¢r _ E(¢r+l )) . The intuition is similar to that discussed in case II: The possibility of a larger price wedge in the next period causes the arbitrageur to hedge against this risk and reduce her demand in the current period (DeLong et a1. (1990)). The reduction in demand is not caused by a margin requirement as in case 11, but by the risk of imperfect substitutes. These results confirm the findings of Wang (1994), who demonstrates that large trading volume induces positive (negative) return autocorrelations when the primary motive for trading is speculation (liquidity). The arbitrageur that invests in imperfect substitutes is similar to the speculator in Wang (1994). Since the price discrepancy cannot be 19 eliminated 1 (B) will COI Case IV: M. positive autt lfa positive efficient pri constraint or “141 — 11 In other \\'0 rePresents t1 cover the m; eliminated immediately at all periods due to imperfect substitution, the price of asset A (B) will continue to increase (decrease) until time T. In other words, there should be a positive autocorrelation on the returns of assets in which the arbitrageur invests. Case IV: Margin constraints and imperfect substitutes If a positive shock occurs for investor A, the price wedge between the new price and the efficient price will become ¢ , that is asset A is underpriced by ¢t' The wealth constraint of the arbitrageur reduces to WM] : Wt +xt (¢t — ¢t+l + 5H1) (1) In other words, she is subject to the volatility of asset A’s payoff and that volatility represents the ftmdamental risk involved in this arbitrage strategy. Moreover, the margin constraint of the arbitrageur implies that she holds enough funds in her margin account to cover the maximum loss that she can face: wt 2 max(xt (_¢l + ¢t+l _ 6r+l)) 6I+l SW, 23—- — x {W ¢l+l) :>x _ wt ’__ 2 6 — ¢1 + (+1 () When (1) and (2) are combined, we get 20 ~ : W, ”1+1 1 1.1-hen a neg case, the we 11‘ 2 11“, 1 +1 A comparisti the next per (negative), t IOVerpriced 1 S.‘Tnmetric f. the assets, OPPOFTUDitie fea‘Sible trad It may be OI becomes p 0 demands 11C TCSUII is n01 \ _ W 1+ (514-1 + (¢t _ ¢t+l)) T _ (3) (6 _ (¢t — ¢r+l )) wt+l I When a negative shock occurs for investor A, asset A becomes overpriced by ¢t . In this case, the wealth constraint and margin constraint imply that (—5t+1 + (¢t _ ¢t+l )) 1 + __ (4) (6 _ (¢t _ ¢r+l )) Wm : W1 A comparison of (3) and (4) reveals us the arbitrageur’s demand difference, depending on the next period’s payoff and the risk premiums. If the next periods payoff is positive (negative), the wealth of the arbitrageur increases more when the asset is underpriced (overpriced) than when it is overpriced (underpriced). Notice that the margin constraint is symmetric for both long and short positions. If the arbitrageur is restricted from shorting the assets, she can only invest in underpriced assets and must bypass the profit opportunities when assets are overpriced. In that case, the equation (2) and (3) give the feasible trading strategy and wealth process respectively. It may be optimal for the arbitrageur not to execute her strategy if the next period payoff becomes positive (negative) when the asset is overpriced (underpriced). In that case, she demands nothing at all periods and lets the mispricing exist until time T. In fact, this result is not surprising because of the conservative margin requirement. 1.3.6 Empirical Implications of the Solutions All these cases present the effects of limits to arbitrage and their effects on the trading activities of arbitrageurs. It may not be possible to distinguish case I from case IV, 21 because if :1 situations. I This is panl spectrum of The similari 11982) is in: arrival of ne if traders bt speculative 1 that they sla- happens due requirements mainly origi PFOduct of in Cases 11 and fully absorb depends on . aversion COe: demand fOr ri Proposition th ere Will be . ’he reguired l because if all mispricing is eliminated instantaneously, there should be no trade in either situations. Therefore, no trade argument becomes equivalent to no arbitrage condition. This is particularly striking since cases I and IV represent the extreme situations in the spectrum of the arbitrageur’s ability to absorb shocks. The similarity between the no-trade result of this model and that of Milgrom and Stokey (1982) is interesting. The latter is often used to argue that in ongoing security markets the arrival of new information cannot generate trade. The usual intuition for this claim is that if traders begin with a Pareto optimal allocation of resources, then any trade is for speculative purposes, so the willingness of one trader to make a trade indicates to others that they should not accept the other side of the trade. In our context, lack of trade happens due to high limits of arbitrage (imperfect substitutes and conservative margin requirements) rather than information asymmetry. Yet, the similarity of predictions mainly originates from the segmented market assumption, which is essentially a by- product of information asymmetry. Cases 11 and III produce an observationally equivalent result since the arbitrageur fails to fully absorb the supply shock. The comparison of arbitrageur’s demand in these cases depends on the level of financial constraint imposed on the arbitrageur and the risk aversion coefficient. Two propositions can now be stated with respect to arbitrageurs’ demand for risky assets. Proposition 1 (no trade — no arbitrage): If the limits of arbitrage are strong enough, there will be no attempt to eliminate possible mispricing and arbitrageurs will not provide the required liquidity to the market. In a frictionless market, the existence of arbitrageurs ensures no mispricing. In both cases, there will be no arbitrage-related demand for assets. 22 Propositior increases th boosts arbt volume. We test the by GKM (2 ilovv) volu: postulate 111.. argument c visibility ant1 visible than information Investors tra rebalancing Opportunity arh Proposition 2 (risky arbitrage): Any mispricing in assets with close substitutes increases the interest among competitive arbitrageurs (increased visibility) and therefore boosts arbitrageurs’ demand for risky asset, which is revealed as abnormal trading volume. We test the second proposition to explain the high-volume premium puzzle documented by GKM (2001). As discussed before, GKM (2001) find that periods of extremely high (low) volume tend to be followed by positive (negative) excess returns, and they postulate that this pattern depends on increased stock visibility or lack of thereof. Their argument can explain increased returns but not the relationship between increased visibility and increased trading activity. Is there any factor that makes some stocks more visible than others? lDoes substitutability makes it easier to capture mispricings or new information, thereby causing unusually high trading activities? Investors trade for at least two reasons: portfolio rebalancing and speculation. Portfolio rebalancing trades may be triggered by many factors, such as changes in investment opportunity sets, investment objectives, and liquidity needs. Speculative trades are mainly based on heterogeneity in beliefs or information sets. We argue that neither motive can be the reason for the increased visibility and trading activity that may explain high volume premium unless the need for trades due to the above factors is positively correlated among all investors. Only arbitrage trades, the very basic motivation to trade, can be positively correlated if there is enough competitive arbitrageurs in the market and if they do not face significant limits to arbitrage. This argument is the flip side of the correlated noise trades and associated noise trader risk (DeLong et al. ( 1990)). One can think of groups of investors 23 A and B a- Shocks that distinguish (Shleifer (2’ depends on investment arbitrageurs increase its We use dat. betvveen Au.E interval betvv 50 trading d trading Illlerv Each lumen-a. last day_ The volume is in Wading V011” Stock if its I A and B as noise traders in their segmented markets, which receive correlated supply shocks that make their trades positively correlated. In this sense, it is not possible to distinguish arbitrageurs from noise traders unless the direction of supply shocks is known (Shleifer (2000)). From this perspective, substitutability risk is related to noise trader risk and it is systematic, and therefore should be priced. Arbitrageurs’ demand for risky assets depends on the degree of substitutability risk (deviation from the fimdamental values), investment horizon, risk aversion, and margin constraints. Therefore, provided that arbitrageurs are competitive, their interest in a certain asset may be strong enough to increase its visibility via abnormal trading activities. 1.4 Empirical Tests 1.4.1 Data and Methodology We use data from Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) on NYSE stocks between August 1963 and January 2001. The sample is constructed by splitting the time interval between August 15, 1963, and .Ian 31, 2001, into 188 nonintersecting intervals of 50 trading clays.‘3 We avoid using the same day of the week as the last day in every irading interval by skipping a day in between each of these intervals. Each interval is split into a reference period, the first 49 days, and a formation period, the last day. The reference period is used to determine how unusually large or small trading volume is in the formation period. The number of shares traded is used as the measure of trading volume.'4 In a given trading interval, a stock is classified as a high (low) volume stock if its formation period volume is in the top (low) 10 percentile of 50 daily ’3 We follow GKM’s method but our test period is five years longer than theirs. ’4 The results were not affected when dollar volume is as a trading activity measure. 24 s l 1 volumes- I statistics ab high volurm At the end c trading volt portfolios 1“ stocks. The suLsequent ‘ All NYSE c Which 50mg merger. a do you prior to the NYSE at some Point i 10 COmpan}. market Capit [lift-“Ugh eigh one are EXCI abOVe. volumes.ls Methods and the terminology we used are illustrated in Figure 1. Descriptive statistics about the sample are summarized in Table 1.1. Overall we end up with 30,832 high volume and 32,148 low volume stocks. At the end of each formation period (the formation date), we form portfolios based on the trading volume classification of stocks for that interval. We construct zero investment portfolios by shorting low-volume stocks and taking long positions in high-volume stocks. The portfolios are held without any rebalancing over the test period, that is, the subsequent 1 to 20 trading days. All NYSE common stocks are considered in any given trading interval except those for which some data was missing. We also removed (1) any stocks that experienced a merger, a delisting, partial liquidation, or a seasoned equity offering during or within one year prior to the formation period; (2) stocks with less than one year of trading history on the NYSE at the start of an interval; and (3) stocks whose price fell below five dollars at some point in the reference period. Also, we divided the sample in three parts according to company size and calculated the return on high— and low-volume stocks. The firms in market capitalization deciles nine and ten are classified as large, those in deciles six through eight as medium, and those in deciles two to five as small firms. Firms in decile one are excluded from the sample because most do not survive the filters described above. 15 GKM uses the highest (lowest) 5 stocks as opposed to top (bottom) 10 percentile. Our approach increases the sample size, which allows us to obtain better substitutability risk estimates of portfolios using the market portfolio as a substitute. The descriptive statistics of our sample is slightly different from those of GKM because of the modified method and the data period. 25 1.4.2 Port At each forr for a total of a total of on (low) \'Olun' formation p. to 20 days. The test peril 5}'NRI : I tne hypothes 1.4.2 Portfolio Formation and Returns At each formation date, a zero investment portfolio is formed by taking a long position for a total of one dollar in all high-volume stocks in a size group, and a short position for a total of one dollar in all low-volume stocks in that same group. Each stock in the high (low) volume category is given equal weight. The position taken at the end of the formation period in each trading interval 1’ is not rebalanced for the whole test period of 1 to 20 days. The test period returns of the long position are denoted by Rih (Ril), and the net position by NRi = Rih - Ril. For the reasons explained later, we use the last 184 periods to test the hypothesis that the average net returns of this strategy over all 184 trading intervals, NR, are positive: __ 1 184 NR =—8—ZZ]VR1. i=1 Note that, in any given interval, only stocks that experience a large enough trading volume shock (positive or negative) are included in the zero investment portfolio. In this respect, this portfolio formation approach is similar to Cooper (1999). The zero investment portfolios are also similar to those used by Conrad et a1. (1994) in that the high-volume side of the position requires an investment of exactly one dollar, whereas the low-volume side of the position generates exactly one dollar at the outset. The cumulative returns of high-volume, low-volume and zero investment portfolios are summarized in Table 1.2. Table 1.3 presents descriptive statistics for cumulative returns of the high-volume and low-volume portfolios. Overall, our results confirm the high 26 volume pre different m volume 510‘ volume ret . Finally. “‘6 period to c cumulative In the discu: sample. A]: infomiation, or earnings period, For t 1984. More interval in o Oflhese filte volume premium documented by GKM (2001) for a longer data period using slightly different methods. The cumulative return differential between high-volume and low- volume stocks is positive and statistically greater than zero. Furthermore, the high- volume return premium is more apparent for small than large companies. Finally, we replicate the same analysis by skipping one more day after the formation period to control for possible short-term buy/sell pressures that can influence the cumulative returns. Results are not significantly different from the findings in Table 1.2. In the discussion of results, we will compare this buy/sell control sample with the original sample. Also, in order to control for further possible announcement effects (new information), we follow GKM’S method and eliminate stocks that experienced a dividend or earnings announcement one day before, the day of, or one day after the formation period. For this purpose, we used I/B/E/S actuals database, which has data available after 1984. Moreover, the five most extreme observations are removed from each trading interval in order to eliminate the effects of outliers. The results are not affected by either of these filters. Before we attempt to reconcile the high-volume premium documented in Table 1.2, we must define the measures used for certain well-documented risk factors, measures of difference of opinion, and substitutability risk. 27 1.4.3 Me; l The substitr regression r where i: I— .f- ‘ - R; cones; approach v. effects on d The intuitio arbitrageurs short Sl in ’ is assumed that [here 3‘ peTfC‘CI SUI): Wmiller ant Well‘diVerSi residu318 as FOI each hi; and the Star 1.4.3 Measure of Substitutability Risk The substitutability risk of a portfolio (P) is measured at time t as the standard error of the regression and sum of the squared residuals of the following OLS: P f _ m _ f Ri _Ri —IB(R1' Ri)+8i’ where i= t—l , t—2, ..., t—k (k determines the estimation window length). Rif corresponds to risk free rate and R,- represents to market return at time 1. Thls approach was used by Wurgler and Zhuravskaya (2002), who analyze substitutability effects on demand curve elasticity.l6 The intuition behind this approach is based on the zero investment portfolio created by arbitrageurs. The implied zero investment strategy is, for every $1 long in portfolio P: short $1 in T-bills, short 8 B in market portfolio, and long 8 B in T-bills. In other words, it is assumed that market should be a close substitute for any diversified portfolio, provided that there are enough stocks in the portfolio. On an individual stock basis, finding a perfect substitute is almost impossible as shown by many studies (e.g., Roll (1988), Wurgler and Zhuravskaya (2002)). Yet, the market should be a perfect substitute for any well-diversified portfolio by construction. We interpret the standard deviation of the OLS residuals as the denominator of the Sharpe ratio. For each high-volume and low-volume portfolios, we calculate the variance of residuals and the standard error of regression by using the previous 150, 200, and 250 days.17 In ‘6 We also used companies with closest B/M and Size in the same industry as close subsitutes in addition to market portfolio. The results are essentially the same. 28 #4..- ‘e— order to Ck and focus substitutalo between 11' stocks haV less signifi l.4.4 .‘lc A possible differ morfi for this f: h)pothesiz 10 aIInOUn | the returns POSiIi\'e 5k mOre Prom SugOeSt ne Opinion: i order to compare the effects of measurement changes, we discard the first four periods and focused on the last 184. Descriptive statistics for empirical distributions of substitutability are reported in Table 1.4. A comparison of substitutability risk difference between high-volume and low-volume stocks supports our conjecture that high—volume stocks have lower substitutability risk (Table 1.4 - Panel C), but, the difference becomes less significant as the estimation period decreases. 1.4.4 Measure of Divergence of Opinions A possible explanation of the observed return premium is that opinions among investors differ more for high-volume portfolios than low-volume portfolios.‘8 In order to control for this factor, we employ two measures suggested by Chen et al. (2001), who hypothesize that managers with some discretion over the disclosure of information prefer to announce good news immediately and allow bad news to emerge slowly. In that case, the returns of such companies should reflect asymmetries that can be captured by the positive skewness of the distribution. They also show that positive skewness should be more pronounced for firms that receive attention from fewer analysts. Therefore, they suggest negative skewness of empirical distributions as a measure for difference of opinion: SK, = — n(n-1)3IZZR;3 (n—1)(n—2)(ZR;) /2’ 17 We also calculated substitutability risk using two-day and three-day returns but the results were unaffected. '8 Analyst coverage and difference between analyst estimates (Diether et al.(2002)) are the two most commonly used measures of difference of opinion. Because of the time interval in our study, we do not use these. 29 is where RP r and n “I“ {Queuing l n, represcr idea of the likely to be 1.4.5 Me In order tr eKamined 1 (Small min and Titmai 5‘ Winner 0 fOI’matiOn liqllidity ( differential N Sam C ‘r' a ._ Se where Rp represents the sequence of demeaned daily returns of the portfolios for period t, and n represents the number of days before the formation period. They also use the following measure, which is based on the second moments of the empirical distributions: “(m -1) 2sz DUVAL, = log DOW” ; (nd _1)Z sz k UP J ‘ V nu represents the number of “up” days, and nd represents the number of “down” days. The idea of the DUVAL (down-to-up volatility) measure is similar to skewness, but it is less likely to be affected by the extreme returns. '9 1.4.5 Measure of Other Risk Factors In order to control for various risk factors suggested in the literature, we use those examined by F ama and French (1992), book-to-market (high minus low, HML) and size (small minus big, SMB ).20 Also, to control for possible momentum effects (Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)), we use an indicator variable that represents whether a portfolio was a winner or loser portfolio with respect to the market for 50,100, and 250 days before the formation period. Using the Trade and Quote (TAQ) database, GKM (2001) show that liquidity (Arnihud and Mendelson (1986)) is not a possible explanation for the return differential between high-volume stocks and low-volume stocks. Therefore, we do not control for the liquidity factor. '9 We report the results for skewness (SK). The results with DUVAL are essentially the same. 20 See http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html 30 1.4.6 T68 We argue substitutab fundament. systematic average re‘ low-vol um puzzle. in order to following I the disturb. be correlat “‘3 a1 j 1.4.6 Tests We argue that higher systematic risk requires a higher expected return and that substitutability risk is systematic, so it should be priced when assets deviate from fimdamentals. Furthermore, if abnormal trading activity is a proxy for positive shifts in systematic substitutability risk, then a positive trading volume shock should precede large average return. Therefore, the return differential between responsiveness of high- and low-volume portfolios to changes in systematic risk should explain the high-premium puzzle. In order to test the effect of systematic risk difference on return differential, we use the following equation system. The seemingly unrelated regression method (SURE) allows the disturbance terms for the high- and low-volume portfolios in each trading interval to be correlated.“ R,” = em + eHMR,“ + flHSSMB, + eHHHML, + ,BHOMzsof’ + flHSKSKrH + flHAA‘tH + 5rH (5) R,” = em + em R,“ + ,BLSSMB“ + ,8”, mm, + ,BLOMZSOf + flLSKSKrL + IBLAALr + 5f (6) In these equations, t=5,..,188; i=1 ..20; and H R” = cumulative i day return on the equally weighted high volume portfolio; 2' We also used OLS to estimate the given system, but differences between the methods do not affect the conclusions. 31 R: =CU] H _ . A ,— star period (sul L _ - ‘. {'1 t— 5131 period (sul Rirm : C L11 S.\IB,= r HML, = ”2 \"OIH daFS befo 3K3”, 5 before the In this se- SecuI’IIIeS Securities Fur-{berm coefficieI N .. OtiCe (”manor L R” = cumulative i day return on the equally weighted low volume portfolio; AH, = standard error of the regression in Section 1.4.3 for 250 days before the formation period (substitutability risk measure for high volume portfolio) 22; AL, = standard error of the regression in Section 1.4.3 for 250 days before the formation period (substitutability risk measure for low volume portfolio); R “m = cumulative market return for the corresponding test period; 511le Fama-French size factor for the corresponding test period; HA/[Lt = Fama-French book-to-market (B/M) factor for the corresponding test period; M25031, M250,L = 1 if high (low) volume portfolio outperformed the market for 250 days before the formation period, 0 otherwise (momentum factor); and SKtH, SK}: negative skewness of the high (low) volume portfolio for 250 days before the formation period. In this setting, the low-volume portfolio is a benchmark for a portfolio of correctly priced securities, and the high-volume portfolio represents a portfolio of possible mispriced securities. Therefore, we expect to estimate a significant BRA and an insignificant BLA. Furthermore, because we are particularly interested in the difference among the coefficients of systematic risks due to other factors, we test the following hypotheses: 22 Notice that the substitutability risk is estimated by using the returns before the formation period. This information is available at the formation date. 32 Hypothesis 1: There is no market risk difference between high-volume and low-volume portfolios, or firm — flLM = 0- Hypothesis 2: Size differences do not explain the return differential of high-volume and low-volume portfolios, or ,BHS — ,BLS = 0. Hypothesis 3: B/M differences do not explain the return differential of hi gh-volume and low-volume portfolios, or flHH — ,8“, = 0. Hypothesis 4: Momentum risk differences do not explain the return differential of high- volume and low-volume portfolios, or [3H0 — ,BLO = 0. Hypothesis 5: Difference of opinion differences do not explain the return differential of high-volume and low-volume portfolios, or ,8ng — flLSK = 0. Hypothesis 6: Substitutability risk differences do not explain the return differential of high-volume and low-volume portfolios, or flHA — ,BLA = 0. Main results are presented in Table 1.5 and two points should be noted. First, confirming F ama and French (1992), market, size and book-to-market factors are significant for both high- and low-volume portfolios, but difference of opinion is not significant for both. Second, the coefficients for momentum and substitutability risks are significant at the 10% level for high-volume portfolios but are not significant for low-volume portfolios. The results are in line with our conjectures, but the statistical significance of substitutability risk is not as high as for the other systematic risk factors. 33 What is l differenCt The resul The differ or the bu:l is, markc portfolios Hypothes and low-x negative I that have cannot ex] The differ for the ori Volume pC The SubSI 31014.0 What is more crucial here is that substitutability risk may explain the return premium difference between the portfolios that experienced positive and negative volume shocks. The results for the six hypotheses are presented in Table 1.6.1.23 The difference in market betas is not statistically significant for either the original sample or the buy/sell pressure control sample. Therefore, hypothesis 1 cannot be rejected, that is, market risk may not explain the return differential between high- and low-volume portfolios. Hypothesis 4 also cannot be rejected. The momentum factor difference between high- and low-volume portfolios is zero before the eighth day, but it becomes significant and negative thereafter. In other words, in the short run, return premium is higher for stocks that have performed relatively poorly during the reference period. Therefore, momentum cannot explain the return differential between hi gh- and low-volume stocks.24 The difference in the skewness of prior distributions is not statistically significant either for the original or the buy/sell sample. Therefore, hypothesis 5 cannot be rejected, that is, difference of opinion may not account for the return differential between high- and low- volume portfolios. The substitutability risk coefficients reveal interesting patterns. The arbitrage risk difference is statistically significant at the 1% level for the cumulative returns from days 3 to 14. Comparison of the substitutability risk coefficient differential in part A and B of 23 We also estimated the same system by using all possible combinations or explanatory variables. The results and conclusions are unaffected. The results presented in Tables 1.6 to 1.8 include all the variables we considered. 24 GKM (2001) reach the same conclusion by using both daily and weekly returns. 34 Table 1-‘ Furtherm substitute portfolio: zero in al lnterestin significar differertec concave a 1.4.7 R. Hmothes: the aboyc Volume P equations POHfolios Table 1.6.2 shows that temporary buy/sell pressures cannot account for this result.25 Furthermore, all significant beta differentials are positive, which indicates that substitutability risk is more likely to be priced in high-volume portfolios than low-volume portfolios. The substitutability risk coefficient difference is significant and greater than zero in all cases from days 3 to 14, so hypothesis 6 is rejected.26 Interestingly, the p-values of the arbitrage risk coefficient difference reveal a U-shaped significance. During the test period, the standard deviation of arbitrage risk coefficient difference is fairly constant, which suggests that the pattern is indeed caused by a concave arbitrage risk coefficient difference. We will address to this issue later. 1.4.7 Relationship between Size and Substitutability Risk Hypothesis 2 cannot be rejected on the basis of the overall sample. In order to understand the above pattern of the substitutability risk difference, we separate high- and low- volurne portfolios according to the company size and test the following systems of equations using seemingly unrelated regression for portfolios of large companies and portfolios of medium and small companies separately.27 H m H Ru 2 IBHC + IBHMRrr + 161155“an + flHHHmit + flHOMZSOr + [BHSKSKtH + IBHAATH + gtH 25 High volume premium documented by GKM (2001) is becomes insignificant around the 15th day. 26 We tested our hypothesis by using different measures for substitutability risk with different estimation periods and confirm the above results in each case with minor differences. 27 We combined medium and small size companies to increase the number of stocks in portfolios in order to create a better substitute for the market portfolio. 3S \then the size high- until the which int 1.7.1 and For medii volume p «’10 not aft Table 1.8 These tm by the ( hWOIhesi SOoner th c0mpanie base. Bet arbitrageu . Lame l1“ estOrs RitL = flLC + flLM Ram + flLsSMBu + flLHHMit + flLOMZSOtL + flISKSKIL + flLAALt + 81L When the same tests are applied to the substitutability risk coefficient differential of large size high- and low-volume portfolios, the differences remain significant at the 5% level until the eleventh day. Most of these effects disappear in the buy/sell control sample, which indicates that immediate returns are more significant for large companies (Table 1.7.1 and Table 1.7.2). For medium and small companies, the arbitrage risk differential between high- and low- volume portfolios is significant after day three. Furthermore, possible buy/sell pressures do not affect the significance of he high-volume premium for this group (Table 1.8.1 and Table 1.8.2). These two observations suggest that the pattern observed for the whole sample is created by the combination of arbitrage and company size. This supports the visibility hypothesis: An arbitrage opportunity in large companies is more likely to be identified sooner than an opportunity in stocks of small and medium companies, because large companies are followed by more analysts and a larger investor (presumably arbitrageur) base. Because small size firms are less visible to a large number of competitive arbitrageurs in a short period, price corrections takes longer time.28 Substitutability of the 28 Large size can be interpreted as a proxy for less information asymmetry between investors and the companies. In this sense, variables that measures transparency, such as index membership and wide coverage by analysts, are all by-products of size. 36 stocks which 1.4.8 Value respect altemzit arbitrag which 5 We reje. between strategic that fact Parts of Premium 1.5 Eco Hed; If it is z TECeiVed 11115336” 7 thaf fill] Li stocks of large companies increases arbitrageurs’ interest and trading volume (visibility), which will reduce the possibility and duration of mispricing. 1.4.8 Explanatory Power of the B/M Ratio Value investors tend to buy high B/M stocks when they become relatively cheap with respect to their fundamental values. Therefore, a high B/M ratio can be viewed as an alternative arbitrage risk measure. Interestingly, the correlation between HML and arbitrage risk is quite small (0.07 for the original sample, 0.11 for the buy/sell sample), which suggests that they capture different aspects of mispricing. For the original sample, we reject the hypothesis 3 after day nine and find that the short-term return difference between high- and low-volume portfolios may also be associated with value investing strategies due to higher factor loadings on the HML factor. Although the significance of that factor is not as strong as the substitutability risk factor, it shows effects in the latter parts of the test period. Therefore, HML may be a viable explanation for high-volume premium puzzle but its significance is not as strong as the substitutability risk. 1.5 Economic Significance of Arbitrageur’s Profits and High-Volume Investing as a Hedge Fund Strategy If it is assumed that the possibility of getting positive or negative information on a particular asset is equally likely in the long run, then the returns due to information received during abnormal trading period should eventually be canceled (diversification of unsystematic risk). Yet, returns obtained from deviations from fundamentals exhibit an asymmetry. Assume that fundamental prices of two perfect substitutes (A and B) are $100. For some reason, 37 asset A is long 105» Mien ass arbitraget Now com 10% and i Once the by 9.090 i. yield a re with abno Symmetrid observed and skewt The strate StockS, an merflbre to be trad described Shows the the magni If it is as mart—en u ParameIEr asset A is underpriced by 10% and sold at $90. In this case, the arbitrageur’s strategy is to long 10/9 shares of asset A and short 1 share of asset B (zero investment), and wait. When asset A reverts to its true price ($100), its price will increase by 11.11%, and the arbitrageur makes $11.11. Now consider another pair of substitutes (C and D) and assume asset C is overpriced by 10% and sold at $110. The arbitrageur shorts 10/11 shares of asset C and longs 1 asset D. Once the prices converge to $100, arbitrageur makes $9.09, and the price of C declines by 9.09%. For an equally weighted portfolio of A, B, C and D, longing all of them will yield a return of 0.505%. This represents the return on the portfolio that contains assets with abnormally high trading activities. Although deviations from fimdamental values is symmetric (i.e., a security can be under priced or overpriced equal likelihood), the observed return on an equally weighted portfolio of mispriced securities is asymmetric and skewed to positive values, as presented above. The strategy of arbitrageurs includes selling overpriced stocks and/or buying underpriced stocks, and presumably their trading activities are signaled as increased trading volumes. Therefore, their profit depends on the price movements of the stocks that are more likely to be traded in high-volume portfolio. We should reemphasize that the situation that is described above does not distinguish which stocks are overpriced or underpriced, but it shows the relationship between average mispricing in an equally weighted portfolio and the magnitude of mispricing. If it is assumed that high-volume portfolios include all the mispriced securities in the market, then the level of correction for mispricing can be estimated. Based on the parameter estimates obtained for the risk factors for lS-day cumulative returns 38 (BHC=0-0031: BHM =1.0295, 0H5 =0.3828, and BHH =0.3707) given in Table 1.5 and the val ues of the average of observations (RH=1.2%, RM = 0.45%, HML= 0.54%, and S MB=0.03%), the return captured by the substitutability risk is 0.23%. In a market where shor‘t selling is not constrained, this premium corresponds to a mispricing of 6.75%. As the selling constraints become binding, however, the return from substitutability risk drops down to 0.23% per 15 days.29 Therefore, as a hedge fund strategy, identification of mi 8 pricing via “positive” volume shocks may produce positive returns, depending on the lev e] of short-selling constraints. 1 -6 Conclusion In this paper, we provide new insights to the visibility hypothesis of Miller (1977), who at gues that increased attention to a given stock (such as heavy trading) should attract and Convince more investors to buy the stock. Therefore, abnormal trading activities should Signal price increases in a market where short selling is restricted. Miller’s argument can explain the relationship between abnormal trading activity and subsequent price increases, but it falls short to explain why particular stocks experience high trading volume in the first place. We argue that stocks with low substitutability risk are more likely to experience abnormal trading activity when their price deviates from fundamentals and we postulate that the abnormal trading activities may signal the intentions of the traders, presumably arbitrageurs. Thus, in an economy where short sales are restricted, stocks with substitutes are more likely to be “visible” when they are underpriced. We have presented empirical evidence that substitutability risk can explain 29 Conrad, Gultekin, and Kaul (1997) estimate that one-week return of less than 1 percent on zero investment portfolios would be wiped out by one-way transaction costs of 0.2 percent. 39 the premium between high- and low-volume stocks (Gervais, Kaniel, and Mingelgrin (2001 )). The arbitrage interpretation of the visibility hypothesis complements Chan and Lakonishok (1993), who suggest that investors typically only consider the assets they hold when making their sell decisions and all assets in the market when making buy decisions. They postulate that the decision about which asset to buy conveys more information to the market than the decision to sell, because sell orders usually are interpreted as liquidity motivated. We maintain that the information effect on trading volume is only one side of the story. In the model presented here, the trading strategies of investors who have access to all assets in a segmented market may not be driven only by information. Investors, who provide the liquidity to other investors with limited investment opportunity sets and who profit from any price discrepancy between markets segments, care about the availability of perfect substitutes (substitutability risk). Their demand for such assets increases the visibility of those assets and forces other investors to consider them. When assets with low substitutability risk are underpriced, increased visibility causes prices to appreciate and expected returns to depreciate. Finally, our approach relates extreme trading volume to the most fundamental motive of trading: arbitrage and its limits and it may shed light to trading activities that cannot be explained by announcement affects, difference of opinion, or liquidity. 4O APPENDIX 1 TABLES AND FIGURES FOR CHAPTER 1 41 003 F com Fm oomvrv mE:_o> c.2022 mmmom 5 $9 $5.59 oE:_o> ommeo>< Soomfi :2. eaten. cosuctouv 323:. @592... 53.. Ho .23.“. o2. co: comm oE:_o> 528.2 82 DR. 5% e22o> Semi 3.35:8 cored 20:55.8": 323:. main... 5m Hm Egan ommv omvm oomvw oE:_o> 5622 3va ommom mmmvmw mE:_o> mmm8>< «ASE met“. E3622 BEE omen; :95 £13.35 252... m8. - oEEmw =2o>o n< Econ. $12:ch wfinmb @8028 5 888m @829, 32 Ho .33 me @3683 Pa 85 86on mo 698:: 36% m Kean .3: couoom E won—Moe fl consuming—o 085:5 304 28 :wE .3385 masons some 8 309m 0823 32 8 ~32 mm commmmflo 2d 36 83on mo 898:: 2: co moumsflm £505 Q 655 .mREBE chwb 63 98 5m 08% mo amp mafia: ofi “26 :83 8m 0 use m 223m E 322: @3385 mafia: =m mo mane wave: 2: 2e 55 :83 £862: 98 mowfiozw 05 co moumuflm 950% < 35$ 10on some 5 than x55 39% 33% mo .5985: 05 $5358 0830> @3on 85-325 05 8 cocwmmmm 8m 2:,“ 3 o>$ 320% E 805 98 430% EFEEBE 05 2 voqwmmmm 8m Emma 3:85 xmm 320% 5 mph: dsem Sandman: 05 8 nocwmmmm 8m :8 was 2:: mozoon cosmfifizmmo «388 5 EEE datum 8:988 05 wfiwooocm So» 05 mo vac ofi um 8:02. souwgfifimo Hoe—88 m: 3 mamweooom 3:on 0N6 ooh: mo 28 E “scammed—o fl xooam m .EEBE some Sm .mmmc om mo flmtoafi wfiumb madame—gone: mm: mo 339:8 mm 0383 ammo 336 22. 2.5% .35 £5 2: E 3:35 333.35 S ezee 42 lllf‘ 0N vm ovF mm mm F mm mam F? Em ow F mm om 3 mo vm F om mam Fama ooF F F mm on .8 B So Ev FE 03 v F Fm mm m F F S Em E FR ow F n F F mu on 3F mm «8 FE FR 8 F m F F ow cm Fm mNF m3 ENE ow v F NN F vm mam mm m5 Em Em om vm mm No Fun no em F3 2 Fflm ov m me n F 5 F n F MK mom :Qw om mm a F av on mm am now F5 FE o F m mm mm mm mm mm mom 5&5 F F oE:_o> oE:_o> oE:_o> oE:_o> mE:_o> oE:_o> ectoa “Eton. 2,3 :9: 26.. :9: 25.. :9... Sneeze“. 95¢ :25 ES... 8:622 mEeE omen; «cocoa 63023 .5— ofim SE 3 Somme. 525 9.005 oE:_o> :9: can 25.. Fo 33:52 am .98....— ow FF mmm mmm Nun omm 25::me o o m 0F 5 F 83.552 NmF QVF Nmm Nam m.mm QNV >wu Em m.w o. FF 0.0m 06m 9mm mdm swim—2 «.9 we one s. 5 m. a OS 8992 oE:_o> oE:_o> oEEo> oE:_o> oE:_o> oE:_o> 2,3 :9: 33 :9... 2,3 :9... 22:35me". on? new 2:23 3 voodoo. 53> 9.02m F0 .382 F0 woumafim 2:35.30 5 Econ. €35.88 3 ezee 43 44 00.0 F0." 00.0 3.0 8.0 8.0 03 F3 .30-. 008.0 200.0 28.0 008.0 008.0 008.0 38.0 0080 m2 08.0- 38.0- F 8.0- 38.0- :80- 008.0- 08.0- 0 80. 0220> 2,3 008.0 008.0 38.0 008.0 008.0 008.0 008.0 008.0 0520> 09: 05E __< d .0000 :80 008.0 008.0 008.0 008.0 88.0 008.0 008.0 mz 080. 08.0- 08.0- 08.0- :80- 28.0- 08.0- 008.0- 0&0_o> 25.. 008.0 008.0 300.0 0080 F080 0080 08.0 0 80 05:.0> 8f 08:“. 090.. no .030 80.0 080.0 58.0 080.0 080.0 008.0 008.0 080.0 mz 08.0- 08.0- 0 8.0. 08.0- 0 F80- 0080.. 80.0. 08.0- 0&0_0> 33 F080 8000 008.0 0080 S80 0800 008.0 008.0 0520> 85 mctr... 8200—)— ”m _mcmn_ 2 F00 0800 F900 0080 38.0 005.0 020.0 008.0 «.2 0000.0 008.0- 008.0 080.0 80.0- F080- 0080. 008.0- 005:5 23 t F00 2 F00 0200 008.0 008.0 008.0 080.0 030.0 0520> 8: 95¢ =me.< _mcmn_ 0 n 0 m 0 0 0 F .0060 a: .8200 003 .EEBE magma. 20:3 05 E 00833 >200 cm 05 mo 0550009 0\0o~ A083? 30: 8989 8 A083? :35 QB 05 macaw mm CSCBE mafia“ £000 .00 >00 «00¢ 03000 0300808 05 wag—c 0833 wfinmb 0,0380 05 0050;? so 0003 mm 020000.300? 0823 00:. 98% 8.64380 05 8 00:30.00 000 02.“ 9 025 00:80 E 0005 0:0 .Qsohw 85-83008 05 8 000E000 00,0 Ems 3:85 030 8:000 E 08.6 05 dsew Em-0w§_ 08 8 Bummmmw 08 :00. 0:0 05: 8:000 2200003300 00058 E WEE 05 62000 “0200808 £000 8 02a 80» 05 F0 0020 05 00 002000 cosmasfifimo 000—008 .085 05 no 00009 000 anew 0N6 0:9 .052? mficmb 008 0000 9 @8880 0050020 000 3080 4020:: 95005 3000 E 038% mmmu £15 05 ..8 30:25 nous—98h 0:825— .580005— EoN NA 0308 vufi m rd mn.N ovN mvfi Fm.N oefi ocfi mo 56 hoooo woooo ooooo Noooo Foooo moooo mwooo vmooo mNooo oNooo tooo vFooo NFooo oooo.o moooo- om Fo.o NNFoo NF 56 mF Ed @056 NoFo.o Foooo snooo ooooo Foooo mmooo vwooo Fmooo onooo whooo Nnooo nmooo “mood omooo nFooo vFooo NFoo.o noooo moooo- NNFoo woFoo moFoo FoFo.o moooo Foooo moooo hoooo NF 56 ooFoo moFoo ooFoo noooo noooo moooo moooo mmooo mmooo oNooo wFooo oFooo m 306 moooo moooo- nvFod mmFoo mNFoo vaoo vFFoo FFFo.o ooFo.o ooooo mmFoo omFoo NNFoo mF Fo.o mNFoo FmFoo 0F 36 0F 56 ovooo Nvooo nmooo nmooo oNooo mNooo NNooo m Foo.o ooFoo NoFoo moFoo omFoo mm 5.0 mm 5.0 FvFoo oNFoo 2. 2. VF 2. NF. FF 2. m €0.53:ch NA 030,—. .80-. 02 mE:_o> 26.. 0&0_o> 000.. 95¢ .2 no .0000 m2 oE:_o> >03 052.; 09: 0:5". 090.. no .mch 02 08:_o> 26.. 05:.0> 80.. 08:“. 8200—). ”m _0cmn_ mz mE:_o> 26.. 08_o> 80.. 05E __msm.< .0000. A050 0: 02.00 003 45 00F .00 00. 00F 00F 00: 00F 00. 00. 0000020000 0F: .00 000.0 000.0 E: 000.0 000.0 000.0 F000 0.0003. 000.0 0000 F000 0000 0000 F000 000.0- 0:0 000 00003000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 :00 05.0 08.0 000.0 0,00 0.0 000.0 08.0 08.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 0000 80 000.0 00.00.). F80 F000 80 000.0 000.0 8.0 8.0 000.0 000.0 000s. 0000000 000.00.... 000.0 00.0.... 003 0:0 50.0 000.0 :00 000.0 000.0 0.0003. 000.0- 0000. «:0. 00:0- 0000. 000.0- 000.0- 000.0- 000.0- 00003000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 20.0 $0.0 30.0 000.0 000.0 0.00 0.0 F80 8.0 000.0 8.0. 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 8.0- 00.00.). F80. F80- 0000. 08.0- 80. F80- 0000. 8.0. 8.0- 000s. mE:.O>>>Ou_ 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.00.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.0003. 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 30.0- 05.0. 0000 03.0 00003000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 08.0 30.0 :00 08.0 .>00 0.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 08.0 00.005. 08.0 0.80 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 08.0 000.0 08.0 000s. 0E=_o> 00.... 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 F 00.00 46 .32 0:0 0:039» :02 0:: 00 0.03005 9.00:: M32 05 mo 0000 :8 0:030: 0000-3 000 88.: 008050 :05 0:0 038 083020.: 0.0 .00 00000000 03800 0:0 30:90:00 0:003:80 0:... .30.. :00000 :0 00000000 00 0:03? w:.00: 0000 0:0 000 8 0.808000 00000000 000 00080 40200:. mfi00b :000 E 0.:E0m ammo 0:09 0.: win: 00:80.8.“ 000.002 0:0 0:515 304 0:0 083.5 :05 05 .«0 0553— .02 000-3 0:. :8 00:30am 038% 0:0 gash—0:05 .3235”.— mA 030% 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 0000020000 0.0.0 000.0 00.0 00.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 .000 0.0.0 0.0003. 000.0- 000.0 000.0 0.0.0 0000. 000.0- 00.0 00.0 80.0 80.0 00003000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 .000 000.0 .000 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.00 0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 ..00 0.0.0 0.0.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 00.00.). 000.0 000.0 000.0 .80 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.2 0.30.60 .0..0... 00.0 000.0 0.0.0 000.0 00.0 000.0 0.0.0 .000 0.0.0 00.0 0.0003. 000.0- .000- 0000. 0.0.0- .000- 000.0- 0.00. 00.0- 00.0- 00.0- 00003000 .000 000.0 .000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.00 0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 ..00 ..00 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 00.00.). wE:_O>>>On_ .000 000.0 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 08.0 08.0 .80 .80 000s. 00.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.0.0 000.0 0.0.0 .000 0.0003. .0..0- ....0- .80- 000.0 000.0- 000.0- 000.0 00.0 .0..0 .000 0000;000- 0000 000.0 000.0 .000 000.0 000.0 .000 000.0 .000 000.0 500 0.0 ..00 ..00 ..00 ..0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 ..00 0.0.0 00.005. ..00 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 0.0.0 ..00 ..00 0.0.0 000.). 0E:.o> 001.: 00 0. 0. .. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0. .. 0.00 €000.30... 0.. 0.00... 47 0.. . 00 . 0... 0w. 0» . 00 . 08.030090 .0. 00. .00 .0 00. 00 0.00.000... 86 N00 ms .0..0 3.0 mad 0.08.3. NRO. .80.. .300. comm. 000m. 0.0m. 002.30% :8... Zoo... . Sod wooed good good Son ...m Soc... Coo... Zoo... food 0 Sod 0.8... 8.8.8.). .wood Rood good 008... 000.... wooed 808.00.). ago... omood wmood Rood Rood Rood 00.002 .25... .000... .80... once... omood good 0003. emu com 00. omm com om. 02.00. 02.08.05 HZDAO> >061. HEDAO.» =6:— AmMm. 8.009%?— o... ..0 .0..0 6.0.80.0 o... :0 .50.... 080008 0.0... baa0.3..0n=m .< .08... .03 .80 oom.om .n. 48 .0. .0 008.0008 ..0.. 03.30.280.30 0.80.. .3 008050 08008 .0 3:033 ..o 0.00. 0... ..o 0020?. 0... 032.0 0 .0000. 8 00.....m. ...0. 82000.3. 08.0 0... .o 0.00.0.0... .030. ....oo.00..oo0o.0.0.. 0... .0 00.0.50 .0 8:0 05 08000.3. m. .0..0. 8 00:.0> .. 08.. .0 830. .8108 o. 0.82.0083 .Ey. .80 0.0. 00... 0.0.. o. 09.2.0088 ..M. 60.0. .80 oomdfluv. ”0.-..- .z. .N-..- ..--.- u. 0.2.3 .0..0-.800. 08...o> >3. 0:0 08...? ...w... ..000 .0. m0. ..o..8m 8 80.0023. 0.... -.o .0..0 0.0.80.0 0... 80.. 008050 0. < .0800. 8 0.00008 0.0.. $085.... ...0 00.800 8 000.088.. $2000.38 0... o. 0.8.0.080 08.2.9. Bo. .80 080.2. ...w... 00 .00....0003 0.0 0.080 .0288 $500.. ..000 a. 8.08000 .0... 00.00.00.300 .0 80000.0 0.0.0.588 0.. 0.00.0 a —-.‘-:.-u:-, Vy Wan U—a—uu..—L 00.0 00.0 00.. .000. 0.00000. 00.000... 0... .0 0.00 00 00000 . . .0 00.. 00.. 200. 00.00200. 0.0 .0 .0..0 00000.0 00 0000.0 000 000 00. 00000 00.08.00 0:00.: .0305300 :0... bzzausumumnam we Nam—aflvowmflmoh. .U —o=am 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 00. 0000020000 0.0. 000 0000 000 000 0.0 0.00-0000. 00.0. 0.0. 0.0. 0... 00.0 0.0 0.0003. 000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0.00.. 0000.0 0000.0 08038.0 00000 ..000 0.00.0 0.00.0 0.00.0 0.00.0 00.. 0.0 .0000 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 00000 .0000 0.20.0.2 00.0.0 00.0.0 0. .00 0000.0 .0000 0000.0 808.000,. .0000 0.00.0 0.00.0 0.00.0 0.000 ..000 00.00.). 0000.0 0000.0 0.00.0 0000.0 0.00.0 0.00.0 000.). 000 000 00. 000 000 00. 00000 00008.00 ammv m—aflfimmoh 69:03”; on: H6 55m an: GO Havana aha—mac:— v—mmh bm—mfiaflufi—mfiflw um— —oflflnm €000.30... 0.. 0.00.0 49 v. 32.0— I! II... . . u ----uahnufin Ania)! §~< 006088800. .5 003.80. 08 8.0 00.088000 5.080000. 05 26:0 03 0.80083. 8000 8000 8,8 60.000 0.8008 03.0383 8.2.0.0": 008.00. .08 888.8% 0 .8 3.08800 0. .0808 08 .8000 :0 8 .. 0.00 88.0888 08 0.805 08.3 0000-03 08 .8 m0 0.8.80 8 0088080 00808 08 .3 0803800 8.0 39880.00. 08.8.1.3 0833-38 0:0 -..mE (.0 0.0.. 5250880030 08 0.2.0.0 .4400 .80 .:< .. 08.00. 8808.8 05 8805 8.088 0.8.80.3 08.. o> .. o - w 0 0 . . . 8.3 so. 080 0 0.5 0.00 o 8 .0 ..08 o 083 00.80 . .3000. 5000000300020 .385 :Mm .0. .. 0 .0 .00 0000 .0. V. .00 .0 08.8800. 083? 0.32.88; on. a 032.0 .08 8.0308 8880808 To 08 0. Quomgv .IOWNE 03.2.36an 08.00. .08 .000 1.. 05 8 0.8.08 333 8088,8080”. 08 .80 .8108 on. ..o 0888 wamvcongoo 05 800088 0% 8.0 £92m . 5.0% .30.. couoom 8 38,880 00 a...“ 0:0 ..2% 00:88.0. 808.038 0.00 08 mo 080.com 03. 08 083080 3008 05. .8 088.0300 03. 0:0 0.0 + .0030. + 0.000.008 + 0.0000028 + 0885.0 + 00.00020. + 0.0.00.8 + an n 0.0 + 0.00 00m .0 0.0.0 008 + 0.0000038 + 03.0008 + 000000.000. + 0.00200. + 00m u 0.... w .0 a 0 H Gun :60 0 2: 0880:. 0033 00. .H0 0 22.3 .002: 5.05 0832.8 0:. 0.08 0.00 ..00 03 . mo. 0 O o 33 mO~ O ._ .3.- m a: 0509:: OLoN 05 .3 mono-”MW— MWflWM—ED 05 wSmS. g atom 52532.: PEN vwfi 2.: mng Igcwu Hun—fl 0. . 0.00.0 000:0 000: 550 50 A-\IIIII.Im‘--n'\ ml- U-A—-nv_t .0000 20.0. .000. .000. .0000 .000. 0.0. __..0.00 .0000 0.0. .000. .000. .0000 60.0. 00002 03.23830 wwwoo- ooooo .Nooo owwmo ommvo 38.. good. EMNN mmooo- omooo- oommo $23 $8.. mmooo .000-om .0000 .0000 ..000 .000. .0000 .000. .0..0. .0000 ..000 .000. .000. .0000 .000. :00. 0830. 03.03830 38.? Noooo good onhmo woovo mowoo mvooo- gob. Sooo- mmooo- nonmo wmwmo Smog .mooo .000-m. .0000 0.0. .0..0. .0000 .0000 .000. ..000 ..000 0.0. .0000 .000. .0000 .000. :00. 0832 03.0.0800 $5.? moooo ooooo wamo mmmvo omomo o.oo.o- oom... :ooo- omooo- woomo vomvo memo. omooo .000-o. 00.00 000.8 000.8 000.8 000.8 000.0. $0.8 $0.8 $0.8 $0.8 80.8 898 898 Ammdv 0830. . 000200.00 .000 0 0000.0 0000.0 0.00.0 000.0 Ira 06.05.0- moood ooooo NVhNo box-v.0 ovowo moood- (fin Xm-un Can Ida an 54m.— Dan 0000.. 0000.0 0.00.0- <=n 0.0:: ozn 02.5.08. 0.. 0.00.. 1“ wza Sin U:& 51 08000.. 88800 0... 8 00.00.08 0.00809... ..08 0... .8 003.03% .00. 0.03 w...0..0..00..00 0... 39.0 m. .0800. 8 0080> 0....- 00080.8..0 00.0.0 00.08.00 0... 300.0 < .0000. 8 0080> 00.... 0080.880 ..0... 00 ..03 00 000.80 00.08.00 0003.00 0080.8..0 0... 30:0 03 80.000.w0. ..000 ..000 .0 .. A0000 w...00.. 08.0.0800 om .58”... 008.2. .00. 80.8....0 om .8 00.08.00 0. .0008 0... “00000 ..0 0.. .. 0.00 88.0.8.8 0... 0.800. 08.0.. 000 03 0... .8 m... 08.000 8 008.0000 00808 0... .3 00.0.0800 0:0 a0.0880000. 008.8800. 0880> 38 000 ..w... .0 0.0.. 8.50.8080 0... 00.00.00 ..< 000 .m< .. 08.00. 0.8.08.8 0... 0.80.. 0880. 0.8.8.8.. 08.. 0> -30 - w 0 0 000.. 0 0 0 0. . . . 8.0.. ..0 08.0 0 0.0 0 0.00 0 8 0 .08 0 08.0 00.00 .A 588.... 30. ...AqumVIMW .0. .. ..8 .0 0omN8..0. 80 t 00. 0 00. 08... 0> -30 - w 0 0 - 0 . . . .. H . 0:00. .00. 0.0 .. b. . A .o 0. E 0.. .. 030.. .0... .8080... 8.8.0808 . o 00.. . AAOWNEV IOWNE 8m . .V 0 . 0 1.. 0.... 8 0.0.08 300.. 80808-080... 00.. 000 .0808 0.... ..0 0880. w...0..0..00..00 0... 8000.00. 8% 00.0 3.54m . 50% .30.. ..0..00m 8 00.800 00 0.0% 000 ...th 08.8.80 808.002.. 0.00 0... .0 0:0...00. 03. 0... 08.0000 .0008 0.... .8 088.0000 03. 0.. H a. 0.... 0.0 + 0.038 + 0.0.0.000. + 0.0000038 + 00.00850 + 00.00028 + 0.0.030. + 2.0. 3 00. + 0.0.008 + 0.0.0008 + 000000008 + .00.... 00.. + 0000000.. + 0.0.00.8 + 00m n 0 .0. 008.00. w...00.. 0... 000.008 800.3 .00.. . . .0”. 0.8.3 ..0008 9:5 w...38.8 0... 0.0.8.00 03 08.8800. 808.008. 0.00 .0... 0... m80D 0.0.000 .0..0 .000. 2.. w80D 00:820.— ...08.00>..~ 0.0N 0... ..0 080.80.. 0883-30-— 05. Au... 00000.u0~. .0... .003). fidDm 0... ..0 02:00.. .00. 20>.» 00800800 :0. .0383 1.88.0. .8. 030,.- 52 .NmN mood- mood- ..mod mwod- «Nod hood oN mmmN mood- mood- mmod mmod- ..mod hood or oood Nood- mood- Edd ovod- Fvod mood or vonN Nood- mood- vnod emod- omod mood t onN mood- mood- mood mmod- mmod mood 0.. m3...- Nood- mood- wood nmod- ovod mood m. mmvN Nood- mood- Nm rd m_-od mmod mood E. mmod wood. wood. om rd oood- mmod god m.. cox-N Nood- mood- ...Nvd mood- ovod mood N.- mnmN .‘ood- mood- .‘med mFod ..vod mood E. thN Food- wood- mo..d m _-od vmod wood o.- mmoe Food- mood- or .-d Suod Nmod wood o omrd oood Nood- mood vmod mmod mood m mode oood Food- omod vood- Fvod mood \- NddN oood wood. wood mmod- wood wood m mooé oood Nood- omwd mmod- ..ood Nood m ommé _‘ood- .ood- vmrd omod- owod wood 0 owmé _‘ood- oood mm ..d vmod- mvod mood m mwmd Food- oood vwod owod- mmod mood N tmd oood ..ood oood- :od oo-od wood .. «ad-«id 008-00%. ofifiofl :fi-zxu 04%03. sad-21m. 0.0-urn _ 0005.829 2.8m 00.0.8.0..— u< .0..0. 0.2.5.50. 00.. 03.; 53 0800:. 080.00 0... 8 00.080... 0.008.008. =07. 0... .8 00:.0>-.~ .00H 0.03 "m .0..0. €058.86. .8. 030,—- ood mod mod Fmd Ed mvd ood om nod mod mod 5d mwd mud mod 0. mod mod mod Nwd mmd m..d mwd or mod oFd mod Fwd vmd mod mwd 5. mod mwd Nod mod Nvd mod Fwd or N..d ord vod mod mmd m...o ¢od me mod mod mod rod to 5d 3d .3 rod Bd nod _‘od vmd two ..Nd m. Pod 3d ood Fod vod ood .de NF ood o..d mod Pod Nnd mwd oNd 2. ..od m_‘d mod mod and vod 5.0 or mod ovd NFd Nod mmd owd td o Nod ..od ..md mod mod mNd ...Vd m mod vmd Nod de mod .VNd Sad N. Pod vmd Fmd oFd m.-d nod mvd 0 ..od mod ord Nod mmd o_-d _-md m 5.0 mmd omd mod NNd 0rd vmd .0 Pod ood mud vod ..md mud vmd m m...o mod mod mod ood mvd mod N mod mmd mNd Nod m-od mlod v-Nd .. ouSnkIm. onx0.@-xwxa onofi-ora ouId-Ira Quad-01m. onsla-zru ouoma-ozn _ 0.0.x .nam wwmc3mxm 83.00822 ..=>=-_ me .9005. 8.0.0000 54 55 omm.. mood- mood- mmod m . od- mood- mood om mob. mood- mood- mwod mmod- mood mood o. mwm.. mood- mood- mmod mwod- :od mood m. m . ..m mood- mood- omod wwod- mmod mood h. .mom mood- mood- omod omod- mwod mood m. mmom mood- mood- Rod wwod- mwod mood m. omo. mood- mood- omod owod- mmod hood w. mmm. mood- mood- mm..o mood- .mod mood m. m. ..m mood- wood- .m.d wmod- mmod mood m. wom.m mood- wood- .m.d .mod- wmod mood . . mw. .m .ood- wood- hm . d mood- mmod mood o. omh. .ood- wood- wo . d oood mwod mood o mmm. .ood- wood- .m.d mwod wmod mood m wmm.. oood mood- .o . d mmod hood mood .- omm. oood mood- Rod mood- m .od mood m mmm. oood mood- mmod mood- mmod .ood m n .w.. oood mood- mm.d omod- mmod .ood w mood oood .ood- mm. d wwod- wwod .ood m hmnd .ood- .ood- mm.d mwod- mmod .ood m m . md .ood- oood no . d mood wood .ood . . [En-3;. xmqm-Mmzm anuOIQ Ian-12¢ mgmnmza EAQLZIQ UAQuUIn 00000.8.5 2.8m 00.0.8.0m .< .0..0.— .0...§0 .0..0 0...... 2.. 00.0.. 08.0.3.0.— .008.00>:. 0.0m 0... ..0 8820.. 08803301. 0:0 -..wi 00000.83. .8... .0002 nay—3m 0... ..0 0.300% .00.. 0.03 08:09:00 =< .0...80m .0.....0U 0.5000...— w...=0m\w8%=m m.m.. 030... omd w. .o mod wwd omd mod w. d om m . .o mod mod omd .md Rd m. d o. m.d mod .od wmd mmd mmd ...o m. nod mod mod o..o mmd nmd omd 0. mod ...o .od 2d w..o ...o o..o m. mod w..o .od ood mmd m.d w..o m. omd o. d .od mod mmd mmd wod w. mod nod .od ood 3d mwd m . .o m. mod mod mod .od mwd ..md mmd m. mod w. .o mod .od mwd mmd mwd .. .od w..o .od .od mmd mmd nmd o. wod m. .o .od mod mmd m . d .md 0 o..o mmd mod mod mmd mwd omd m mod 3d ...o mod .md mwd mmd 0 mod wad .md w. .o omd mmd .md m mod .od m. d o..o m.d mmd mmd m mod mod mod mod mmd m . d Rd w mod mwd m.d mod mwd wmd mmd m nod o..o wwd .od mwd o..o mmd m mwd nod mod .od 3d mod mmd . drain-<00 $005-00.... onofi-ozn ouzfi-xzm. ou00n-0zm. onzfi-zé on0-.d-0=n . 0.0.8 ...0m 00003008 808080.). 8.2.7. 9.8 88.0.). 80.0009 0.8000: 080.00 0... 8 00.080... 0.00508»: :07. 0... .8 000.0>-.~ .00... 0.0.5 .m— .0..0.— .025080. 0.0.. 2...... 56 57 mwm. mood- wood- wood oood- mmod hood om h . 0.. mood- wood. wood mo. d- wwod wood o. doc. mood- mood- mmod oood- mmod mood w. wmw. mood- wood- mmod mo..o- wmod hood 5. om... mood- mood- oood wwod- omod hood 0. wmmd mood- mood- omod mmod- mmod ..od m. 00 . .. mood- wood- wo . d omod- wwod mood w. doom mood- wood- m. . d mmod- wwod mood m. new. .ood- wood- om.d omod- wwod mood m. mw. .m .ood- mood- wm. d mmod- wmod wood .. mmmm .ood- mood- mood . .od- wmod wood o. .m . .m .ood- mood- ..o..o wmod oood mood o mmnm oood mood- oood o.od m.od .ood w momm .ood- mood- o..od m .o.o- mwod mood n omom oood mood- Sod omod- omod .ood o mmn. .ood- mood- ... ..o wood- wood mood m w . 0.. .ood- mood- oood mmod- mmod mood w wwm. .ood- .ood- oo . d wood omod .ood m m. ... oood oood .m . d wood- wwod oood m mmnd oood oood .mod mwod- mmod oood . Sabin van-vii eqn-ozd :fl-zmn m-fi-mzn E-fi-Zfi ufi-omn . .mou:o.8.....n. 2.2m 3.25%... "< .25.. 295$ .95 E5 2: .55 8.3.25. E2582: PEN 2.. .c 2.2.2:. 9823-39. .25 Awfi. 83033. .2...- .o..c.>. “5.3m 2.. ..o 3.58”. .88 25$ 8.52.8.5 ofim own... 6.2.8.5 13.3.0 .8. «fish. omd mod omd wmd mod ...o w..o om mmd mod m.d mmd wod w..o ood m. mmd w..o wmd .md mod o..o m.d w. w..o nod ...o mmd wod ..od ...o n. o..o omd mod omd mod w..o mod 0. and .md wod mmd ...o omd .od m. mmd mmd mod nod ..md w..o mod w. mod o..o m.d wod o..o o..o o..o m. ...o wmd m.d mod mmd w . d o. d m. mod mmd w..o mod .md mwd wmd .. mod omd o..o ...o mwd .md omd o. wod ..m d m.d mod mod mwd mmd 0 .od mud m.d w..o omd mud wed w mod mm d mmd hmd mwd wmd wwd n ood ood o..o omd wmd mmd mod 0 mod ood w..o nod .dd w..o wwd m mod o..o mod o..o omd mwd hmd w mod w. d omd .od mad mwd wmd m mod mwd mwd w. d cod mod 3d m mod omd mwd omd omd ...o mud . onfid-Ed onxmfibazd duofibzd our-flimm. onmfi-mzd ongm-zfi onufi-umn . v7.9. .....m mmodgoxm 83.883). .2... mzm .33.: 3.8250 .2532. .5330 2.. ... 123...... £352.... .... 7. 2.. ...... mos—57.. ...o... 23$ .m. .23.. 2.2.33.5. ...... 2...“... 58 59 oowd mood- mood- mmod wo . d- owod wood om omod wood- wood- .mod mm. .o- mwod wood o. mend mood- mood- omod om.d- omod oood w. ...od mood- wood- wmod h. ..o- .wod wood h. mwhd mood- mood- wmod wm.d- owod oood w. .ond mood- oood- mwod w. ..o- wwod oood m. wmhd- mood- oood- owod oo. .o- omod m .od w. ..m.d mood- mood- oood .dod- omod o.od m. moo. mood- wood- wwod m. ..o- owod hood m. owhd mood- mood- mo.d mo.d- omod hood .. mho. mood- wood- mo. d .hod- o . od oood o. .om. mood- wood- oood omod- wood mood o woo. .ood- wood- mood Cod .mod- oood w mob. .ood- wood- wmod m.o.o .mod- mood h wom. .ood- mood- mmod omod- oood mood o woo. .ood- mood- omod wwod- oood mood m o . .\-.o .ood- mood- mwod oood wmod mood w m . ...o mood- mood- owod o.od- wmod mood m homd .ood- mood- .m . d hood- wmod mood m wmwd .ood- oood mmmd wmod- mm. .o oood . ...o-«in Vim-yea ofi-ozn ...o-2.... ”SQ-mg ...o-2.... 390v... . .82.o..o.....a. 2.2m 3.25.... 2. .23.. 295$ .95 ...... 2: .55 3.3.3.5.. 238.32.. o..oN 2.. .... 25.2.... «Ea—c.7251. ...... Aw... mommouwoy. .....h. .35.). ”my—3m 2.. ..o 3:53. .88 255 8.5....80 ofim mw.... 6......nm .9280 2.58.... ma...om\w.....=m. m... 3......- mwd mod omd wmd mod .md o..o om mod mod w . d 0nd Ed w..o mod 0. omd mod mod mmd 8.0 mm... mod w. owd mod o..o mm d mod .md mod ... mwd wdd ood mwd .od m ..o wdd 0. omd m. d mod mwd mod w . d mod n. mmd . . d .od mwd mod amd ood w. .0d d. d mod m. d mod mm... .0... m . mmd 8d mod ...o mod mmd mod m. dwd m. d mod ood wod wmd wdd .. omd w. d mod 8d Ed omd 8d d. o . d m. d wdd mmd ood mod add 0 omd wmd mod m.d Rd wwd wod w 8d .md mod wmd .md omd dmd n m . d wmd 8d 00d Sd wwd wmd 0 mod omd mod mod mmd mwd wwd m .md omd mod 0. d do. and o..o w mmd wod mod .md and .0d w.d m omd .3. mod ood mod mmd omd m w..o m.d mwd .od omd mod o0d . H<.%9 "M. 3...... €35.50. 3.. 2%,. 60 wmmd mood- oood- omod mood omod- mood om hvmd mood- ooo.o- ooo.o omod ~mod- mood 2 ~om.m mood- o_o.o- mwod omod :od- mood 2 End mood- oood- onod Sod- wmod Sod S wnmd mood- ooo.o- ooo.o omod wood mood 3 mRm mood- wood- mm_.o mmod hood mood m _ doom mood- mood- om fl d owod oood- mood .1 wmmm mood- mood- om _ .o wmod o_od- mood m— 2 mm mood- mood- hmo d omod mood- mood m_ mem mood- wood- wmod mwod o_o.o flood 2 mg.“ mood- vood- mm _ .o mwod omod wood 3 vwmg oood- mood- 22d do fio mmod mood o oomg ooo.o ooo.o- mmod god wmod mood m an.” ooo.o ooo.o mmod mwod o_od mood N. omvg ooo.o ooo.o mwod wmod- mmod mood c owe; ooo.o Hood- ”mo .o wmod- hood ooo.o m owe; ooo.o ooo.o o3 .o ooo.o- mmod ooo.o v. ova Sod- ooo.o ooo.o omod- omod flood m oQ-d mood- ooo.o mood- mmod omod- mood m omvd Hood- oood ooo.o- do _.o mwod mood o «Sn-[En vii-23a o-fl-OIQ En-zzm moo-ea zoo-2E. van-Ba _ mam—catch 25.532: PEN 2: .«c macs-Sm @829?ch can 8:59:80 «Em 8.552 .3953me 33m 3383mm— “< Edam 295m .55 £5 2: ”55 ...E: 8:2me .2: 3...: exam 2.. a. £33. .5. 25$ 25 =«Em JEEam 353.5 :3 2.3 61 ood mmd ood mwd mmd :d wwd om ood o _ .o ood mmd Ed wwd Ed 3 ood omd ood w _ .o mud cud mod 2 ood omd ood n _ .o ood omd mwd 2 ood mmd ood ood mm d ood omd S ood 2d ood mod wwd ~wwd 3d 2 ood 2d 8d do w _ d and 3d 3 5d m g d mod mod mmd and mwd m ~ ood vmd mod vod Ed omd and m_ ood wmd mod mod Ed and omd 2 mod w o .o nod mod \- _ .o ood mmd do ood mmd omd vod ood mod 2d a mod omd mwd nmd wmd wwd mwd w mod wwd mod mwd wwd mwd wwd \- mod 3d wad omd mwd mmd omd o ood omd mud ood mwd ood ood m ood wwd ood wod omd wmd mod V dd _m.o wwd wwd Ed mmd mwd m nod mod wwd mwd mwd mud ood m m fl d mod wwd ood vmd :md m-fid fl ouSo-fifi ouvafi-xmzd omega-omd ouz-fi-zzm o-I-Sm-mzo onzfi-zzld ooud-uzo m vim ham mmocaoxm 835802 423 mzm 8x82 89800 .363: 55.30 2: E 328:2: £853»: :5 Z 2: ..8 82.3% 30,—- 255 um .95?— Qozfifieuo fix; 2:3. 62 63 Shm _oo.o- o_o.o- mmod omod mwod- mood om mnom mood- :od- omod omod oood- _oo.o a mowm mood- :od- God mmod amod- Sod M: mm_.m mood- ofiod- mmod wood wmod- ooo.o N.— mom.m Hood- :od- wood wood- wood oood- @— oam Sod- o_od- mood omod wood- Sod m— oomm mood- oood- ; H d o o od m _ od- Sod w: momm mood- wood- mid mood mmod- Sod 2 who; mood- oood- wwo d wmod mmod- Sod m— ~ 3.: Sod- mood- om _ d owod wmod- ooo.o 2 mm:m flood- wood- mid mwod Sod- _ood- o: mom; _oo.o- mood- wmfid omod wwod mood o nmwd ooo.o- mood- wmod mofid wwod mood w 2 H; ooo.o mood- owod wood wood- Sod 5 oz.“ ooo.o ooo.o mood mmod \- ~ od- ooo.o o owod Hood flood- . mood whod- Sod ooo.o m womA flood Hood- Hmfio omod- mmod Sod- w :2; ooo.o ooo.o mid oood- mmod mood- m ohwd ooo.o ooo.o mofid wood- wmod Sod- m fwd ooo.o- ooo.o 5:o mwod omod flood _ «Jo-win xm-fi-zmzd 05-03 :fi-zzn mfi-mzd sin-Ema 00 -0:mfi m .mouaohoba 092m vegan—gm "4. ESE 295m ammo £5 2: ”£5 mom—020m 25.532: PEN 2: .«0 30:50am 083007301— 25 AH: mommohwum 2::- 3—5—2 HMDm 2: .«0 333% 39—. 255 8:59:00 “Em 83:00: :00 =«Em Jan—am 3.5000 0.5295 wE—Emfifimzm mdé 030,—- So owd ood ood omd mod mud om ood two ood mwd omd cod Rd 0— ood mmo ood owd mod omd wwd M: ood Rd ood mmd who end mod 2 ood omd ood mmd go mad mwd E ood de ood mod Kd ood wwd m _ 5d mmo ood mod Rd mud mud w: 5d omd ood Sd wmd mmd who 2 mod mmd So mod wed omd wwd m: mod owd mod mod wwd mwd 00.0 S ood mwd woo 8d omd mud Rd 0: mod wmo mod mod mmd omd awd o wmd wwd 2d woo :d omd mmd w So who wmd omd mmd mwd mud \- wod mud mod wmd Rd Rd do; 0 ood wwd Kd 2d 2d who mad m mod mmd mwd woo Gd mwd Gd w So who who mod omd omd and m mod mod omd ood mwd wmd mod m moo ood So 2d mod ood wwd ~ oHSfl-Sfi ngSo-xmzfi oHSn-ozd onEn-zzn onmfi-mzn o-I-Efl-Ezq oHu-fi-uzm— m 03M .nzm mmoc>>0xm 8300802 42: mEm “8.82 “83.300 .wficaofl 08300 2: E 6300:5— flmofioamfl :5 Z on: .— A:0=:::0Uo m.w.— 030,—. OH m0=_a>um «moh- fl—ag um— EEQQ 64 .m 00:00 8000800.: 05 0000 x00 005080 wcaaim 00:0 00:00 0000 08 wfitflm 3 03800 005080 0000000 03 $080008 =0m>fifi $00080: 000 38800 00 00000 E ._ 00:00 80008000 08 80:0 00:00 0000 05 0083.0 080 Coomo .00 :0 002,000 003020.: 03 63800 38-: 2: 00m .9900 om 0: o 803000000 05 00>0 0000305 0: 0080800000 805 080 £00 :03 05 00 000 08 :0 00880: 000 mom—0:000 6.80008 mu: :0 003m 3:800000 o_ 80:03 :85 00 BEBE 008008 08 00880 $0839» 380 :0 02800000 o: no: 083 308088 00 >00 :03 08 w880 0820> w8008 005053 050-008 0: 00m: 000 @900 ow 03c 05 “BEBE wad—00: £000 5 .930 $500: om :0 3000800 20385 @800: mm" 05 m0 nonm— .:0:00_0m 0.08.5 00.: 00:05—00m 08C. 3 2:08 65 _+_ 002005 @800:- 3020500 3 2:0: _ 00:08— 9000.:- SS 0 2% 03 _ 8:00 SEE-50 030 $0 _ 00:00 000..- _ 00:00 00800000: A V A Y _ _ _ _ _ _ om 800 on 0w :0 N 000 _ :0 0.5 00.0 :0 :0 N :0 _ 30 f [V A v 66 BIBLIOGRAPHY REFERENCES FOR CHAPTER 1 67 BIBLIOGRAPHY Admati, A. R., and P. Pfleiderer, 1990, Direct and Indirect Sale of Information, Econometrica 58, 901-928. Ali, A., L. Hwang, and M. A. Trombley, 2003, Arbitrage risk and the book-to-market anomaly, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 355-3 73. Amihud, Y., and H. Mendelson, 1986, Asset Pricing and the Bid Ask Spread, Journal of Financial Economics 17, 223-249. Arbel, A., and P. Strebel, 1982, The neglected and small firm effects, Financial Review 17, 201-218. Bamber, L. S., and Y. S. Cheon, 1995, Differential Price and Volume Reactions to Accounting Earnings Announcements, Accounting Review 70, 417-441. Barberis, N., 2003, A Survey of Behavioral Finance, University of Chicago Working Paper. Blume, L., D. Easley, and M. Ohara, 1994, Market Statistics and Technical Analysis - the Role of Volume, Journal of Finance 49, 153-181. Bollerslev, T., and D. Jubinski, 1999, Equity trading volume and volatility: Latent information arrivals and common long-run dependencies, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 17, 9-21. Campbell, J. Y., S. J. Grossman, and J. Wang, 1993, Trading Volume and Serial- Correlation in Stock Returns, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 905-939. Campbell, J. Y., and A. S. Kyle, 1993, Smart Money, Noise Trading and Stock-Price Behavior, Review of Economic Studies 60, 1-34. 68 A-—-n- Chan, L. K. C., and J. Lakonishok, 1993, Institutional Trades and Intraday Stock-Price Behavior, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 173-199. Chen, J ., H. Hong, and J. C. Stein, 2001, Forecasting crashes: trading volume, past returns, and conditional skewness in stock prices, Journal of Financial Economics 61, 345-381. Chen, J ., H. Hong, and J. C. Stein, 2002, Breadth of ownership and stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 66, 171-205. Clark, P. K., 1973, Subordinated Stochastic-Process Model with Finite Variance for Speculative Prices, Econometrica 41, 135-155. Conrad, J ., M. N. Gultekin, and G. Kaul, 1997, Profitability of short-term contrarian strategies: Implications for market efficiency, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 15, 379-3 86. Conrad, J. S., A. Hameed, and C. M. Niden, 1994, Volume and Autocovariances in Short-Horizon Individual Security Returns, Journal of Finance 49, 1063-1063. Cooper, M., 1999, Filter rules based on price and volume in individual security overreaction, Review of Financial Studies 12, 901-935. D'Avolio, G., 2002, The market for borrowing stock, Journal of Financial Economics 66, 271-306. Delong, J. B., A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers, and R. J. Waldmann, 1990, Noise Trader Risk in Financial-Markets, Journal of Political Economy 98, 703-73 8. Diether, K. B., C. J. Malloy, and A. Scherbina, 2002, Differences of opinion and the cross section of stock returns, Journal of Finance 57, 2113-2141. Epps, T. W., and M. L. Epps, 1976, Stochastic Dependence of Security Price Changes and Transaction Volumes - Implications for Mixture of Distributions Hypothesis, Econometrica 44, 305-321. Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1992, The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 47, 427-465. 69 Foster, F. D., and S. Viswanathan, 1990, A Theory of the Interday Variations in Volume, Variance, and Trading Costs in Securities Markets, Review of Financial Studies 3, 593- 624. F root, K. A., and E. M. Dabora, 1999, How are stock prices affected by the location of trade?, Journal of Financial Economics 53, 189-216. Geczy, C. C., D. K. Musto, and A. V. Reed, 2002, Stocks are special too: an analysis of the equity lending market, Journal of Financial Economics 66, 241-269. Gervais, S., R. Kaniel, and D. H. Mingelgrin, 2001 , The high-volume return premium, Journal of Finance 56, 877-919. Gromb, D., and D. Vayanos, 2002, Equilibrium and welfare in markets with financially constrained arbitrageurs, Journal of Financial Economics 66, 361-407. Harris, M., and A. Raviv, 1993, Differences of Opinion Make a Horse Race, Review of Financial Studies 6, 473-506. Heaton, J ., and D. J. Lucas, 1996, Evaluating the effects of incomplete markets on risk sharing and asset pricing, Journal of Political Economy 104, 443-48 7. Holthausen, R. W., R. W. Leftwich, and D. Mayers, 1990, Large-Block Transactions, the Speed of Response, and Temporary and Permanent Stock-Price Effects, Journal of Financial Economics 26, 71-95. J arrow, R., 1980, Heterogeneous Expectations, Restrictions on Short Sales, and Equilibrium Asset Prices, Journal of Finance 35, 1105-1113. Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers - Implications for Stock-Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65-91. Jones, C. M., and O. A. Lamont, 2002, Short-sale constraints and stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 66, 207-239. Karpoff, J. M., 1986, A Theory of Trading Volume, Journal of Finance 41, 1069-1087. 70 Kreps, D. M., 1977, Note on Fulfilled Expectations Equilibria, Journal of Economic Theory 14, 32-43. Kyle, A. S., 1985, Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica 53, 1315- 1335. Kyle, A. S., and W. Xiong, 2001, Contagion as a wealth effect, Journal of Finance 56, 1401-1440. Lamoureux, C. G., and W. D. Lastrapes, 1990, Heteroskedasticity in Stock Return Data - Volume Versus Garch Effects, Journal of Finance 45, 221-229. Lee, C. M. C., and B. Swaminathan, 2000, Price momentum and trading volume, Journal ofFinance 55, 2017-2069. Littner, J ., 1969, The aggregation of Investor's Diverse Judgements and Preferences in Purely Competitive Strategy Markets, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 4, 347-400. Liu, J ., and F. Longstaff, 2003, Losing monet on arbitrages: optimal dynamic portfolio choice in markets with arbitrage opportunities, Review of Financial Studies (forthcoming). Llorente, G., R. Michaely, G. Saar, and J. Wang, 2002, Dynamic volume-retum relation of individual stocks, Review of Financial Studies 15, 1005-1047. Loderer, C., J. W. Cooney, and L. D. Vandrunen, 1991, The Price Elasticity of Demand for Common-Stock, Journal of Finance 46, 621-651. Lucas, R. E., 1978, Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy, Econometrica 46, 1429-1445. Mayshar, J ., 1983, On Divergence of Opinion and Imperfections in Capital-Markets, American Economic Review 73, 114-128. Merton, R. C., 1987, A Simple-Model of Capital-Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information, Journal of Finance 42, 483-510. 71 Milgrom, P., and N. Stokey, 1982, Information, Trade and Common Knowledge, Journal of Economic Theory 26, 17-27. Miller, E. M., 1977, Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion, Journal of Finance 32,1151-1168. Mitchell, M., T. Pulvino, and E. Stafford, 2002, Limited arbitrage in equity markets, Journal of Finance 57, 551-584. 0' Hara, M., 1995. Market Microstructure Theory (Blackwell Bublishers, Cambridge, MA). Richardson, M., and T. Smith, 1994, A Unified Approach to Testing for Serial- Correlation in Stock Returns, Journal of Business 67, 371-399. R011, R., 1988, R2, Journal ofFinance 43, 541-566. Scholes, M. S., 1972, Market for Securities - Substitution Versus Price Pressure and Effects of Information on Share Prices, Journal of Business 45, 179-211. Shalen, C. T., 1993, Volume, Volatility, and the Dispersion of Beliefs, Review of Financial Studies 6, 405-434. Shleifer, A., 1986, Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down, Journal of Finance 41, 579-590. Shleifer, A., 2000. Ineflicient Markets (Oxford University Press). Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny, 1997, The limits of arbitrage, Journal of Finance 52, 35- 55. Smirlock, M., and L. Starks, 1985, A Further Examination of Stock-Price Changes and Transaction Volume, Journal of Financial Research 8, 217-225. Tauchen, G. E., and M. Pitts, 1983, The Price Variability-Volume Relationship on Speculative Markets, Econometrica 51, 485-505. 72 Wang, J ., 1993, A Model of Intertemporal Asset Prices under Asymmetric Information, Review of Economic Studies 60, 249-282. Wang, J ., 1994, A Model of Competitive Stock Trading Volume, Journal of Political Economy 102, 127-168. Wurgler, J ., and E. Zhuravskaya, 2002, Does arbitrage flatten demand curves for stocks?, Journal of Business 75, 583-608. Xiong, W., 2001, Convergence trading with wealth effects: an amplification mechanism in financial markets, Journal of Financial Economics 62, 247-292. 73 Chapter 2 2 Tests of Competing Theories of Momentum: Market Intelligence and Statistical Arbitrage 2.1 Introduction The simple investing strategy of buying prior winners and selling prior losers, now dubbed momentum, appears significantly profitable both statistically and economically in both US (Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)) and other major markets (Rouwenhorst (1998, 1999) and Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003)). As an example, in the US, from 1965 to 2000, stocks in the t0p six-month return decile beat stocks in the bottom decile by 5.59% (p- value = 0.00), on average, during the subsequent six months. This finding is interesting because it suggests that prices are not weak form efficient. In general, we can summarize the momentum literature in terms of their interpretation of the sorting procedure that is employed in the empirical setup. Let us assume that realized returns can be decomposed into a sum of unconditional expected return and unexpected return, rm '"" nut + gin. Explanations based on rational expectations (such as Conrad and Kaul (1998) and Johnson (2002)) argue that the sorting procedure classifies securities with respect to their expected returns (pi); Therefore momentum profits reflect the risk that is inherit in expected returns. On the other hand, explanations based on behavioral explanations argue 74 that sorting on realized return is mainly dominated by the effect of unexpected return (8"), hence firm specific risk should be the driving factor behind momentum profits (Jegadeesh and Titman(1993), Barberis, Shleifer and Vishny (1998)). Although many studies empirically compare the relative explanatory power of these two explanations, none test these two competing hypothesis using out-of-sample data. In this study, we fill this void in the literature. Our first hypothesis is that, if momentum profits are due to the idiosyncratic risk of securities, as argued by behavioral models of momentum such as Hong and Stein (1999) and Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), then countries that have high asset price comovements should not exhibit momentum profits. In our tests, we show evidence consistent with this hypothesis, suggesting that momentum strategies rely on firm-specific rather than well-known systematic risks. This evidence is also consistent with other studies such as Liew and Vassalou (2002), who show that the growth rate of GDP cannot be captured by momentum strategy profitability, and Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003), who show that macroeconomic risk cannot capture the difference between momentum profitability in an international context. Exploiting the relation between asset price comovements and country-specific factors, we develop empirical tests to study determinants of momentum profitability. We present three novel findings. First, momentum is more pronounced in countries that have severe earnings management practices, suggesting that momentum is not due to market underreaction that is related to eamings-related information. This finding is not consistent with Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996) who show that, in the US, past return and earnings surprise predict large drifts in future returns after controlling one another. 75 Moreover, in some countries where momentum strategies are more profitable, winners and losers subsequently experience reversals in their stock prices, which suggests that profitability of momentum strategies may be due to overreaction induced positive feedback strategies of the sort discussed by DeLong, Shleifer, Summer, and Waldman (1990). However, this pattern is not common to all markets analyzed in this study. Second, momentum strategies appear to be profitable in countries that have more SOphisticated investors. Findings indicate that in sophisticated markets, firm-specific information can be used to infer more informative prices; hence investors make better decisions. This is consistent with Roll (l988)’s predictions: higher firm-specific return variation as a fraction of total variation signals more information-laden stock prices. High stock price synchronicity represents a failure to incorporate firm-specific information into market prices, as discussed in Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000) and Durnev, Morck, Yeung, and Zarowin (2003), and momentum profits are more pervasive in markets where firm- specific information can be incorporated into prices. Third, after decomposing momentum profits into two parts as suggested by Hogan, Jarrow, Teo, and Warachka (2004), trading profit per unit of time and the growth rate of a trading strategy’s volatility (exploitability risk), we document that investor sophistication is positively related to exploitability risk, suggesting that momentum strategies are riskier in markets dominated by sophisticated investors. In other words, exploitability risk is the price of momentum profits. Thus, we conclude that momentum explanations based on rational expectations are capable of explaining differences in momentum profitability across countries. Our results 76 indicate that a combination of earnings management and investor sophistication explain about 40% of the cross-sectional differences of momentum profitability in 31 countries. Findings are robust after controlling for country-specific factors including investor protection, market size, and industry concentration. The rest of the paper is organized in four sections. In the following section, we briefly review the related literature in momentum and asset price comovements. In the third section, we present a simple economy where momentum profits are generated with the idiosyncratic risks of individual stocks. In the fourth section, we describe our data and tests, and report the results of the hypotheses in three parts: (1) momentum profits and asset price comovement, (2) determinants of momentum profitability, and (3) risk of momentum strategy arbitrage and investor sophistication. The fifth section offers conclusions and directions for future research. 2.2 Related Literature Our study is related to two different streams of finance literature: asset price synchronicity and momentum. Morck, Yeung, and Yu (2000) show that two factor model R2 (with US. and local market factors) and other measures of stock market synchronicity are higher in countries with relatively low per-capita GDP and less-developed financial systems. These results imply that the stocks markets in emerging economies may be less useful in terms of processing information and guiding capital towards its best economic use. Moreover, they imply that stocks markets in underdeveloped countries act as ‘side shows’ in the sense that stock market performance does not influence managers’ investment decisions (Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1990)). 77 Durnev, Morck, Yeung and Zarowin (2003) and Campbell, Lettau, Malkiel, and Xu (2001) document a radical decline in the R25 in the US over the last century, which indicates that we may be able to learn about profitability of certain trading strategies not only from the level of stock prices but also from second or higher moments of stock returns. Jin and Myers (2004) argue that these findings are mainly driven by the risk- bearing division between inside managers and outside investors. Our study distinguishes itself from this strand of literature by showing the relationship between investor sophistication and asset price comovement. In other words, we focus on the effects of the investment environment on exploitability of momentum strategies, rather than investigating the reasons why particular countries end up with current investment environment. Most studies agree on the existence of momentum profits. An exception is Lesmond, Schill, and Zhou (2004), who present evidence that profits from momentum strategies may not be large enough to cover transaction costs. Despite the near unanimity with regard to the existence of momentum profits, there are diverging opinions on why it exists. Some argue that momentum profits can be attributed to firm-specific returns. For instance, Lo and MacKinlay (1990) show that momentum could be caused by autocorrelation in returns, lead-lag relations among stocks (cross-serial correlation), or cross-sectional dispersion in unconditional means.1 Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) show ' lntuitively a stock that outperformed other stocks in the past might continue to do so for three reasons: (1) the stock return is positively autocorrelated, so its own past return predicts high future returns; (2) the stock return is negatively correlated with the lagged 78 that momentum is not driven by market risk. Fama and French (1996) demonstrate that Fama and French (1992) unconditional three-factor model cannot explain momentum. Conrad and Kaul (1998) argue that cross-sectional differences in expected returns explain the profitability of momentum returns, whereas Grundy and Martin (2001) measure conditional exposure to three-factor risk and show that neither industry effects nor cross- sectional differences in expected returns are the primary cause of the momentum. Jegadeesh and Titman (2002) argue that cross-sectional differences in expected retums explain very little, if any, of the momentum profits. Johnson (2002) shows that a highly persistent shock to the dividend growth rate can produce momentum patterns in a rational expectations setting. His model predicts momentum profits which can decline rapidly (as observed empirically), but remain positive at longer horizons. Berk, Green and Naik (1999) offer a model based on economic risk factors that affect firm investment life cycles and growth rates. In their model, a firm’s value depends on interest rates as well as the number and systematic risk of its existing projects. Slow turnover in the firrn’s project portfolio leads to persistence in both the firm’s asset base and its systematic risk, all of which makes expected returns positively correlated with lagged expected returns. Simulations results of this model produce momentum profits that are roughly equal to the magnitude observed in the US. at slightly longer horizons. Behavioral approaches such as Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), and Hong and Stein (1999) argue that imperfect formation and revisions of investor expectations in response to new information causes momentum returns on other stocks, so their poor performance predicts high future returns; and (3) the stock simply has a high unconditional mean relative to other stocks. 79 patterns in stock data. Chordia and Shivakumar (2002) investigate the one-step-ahead forecasts obtained by projecting momentum profits onto lagged macroeconomic variables and conclude that US. momentum profits are completely explainable using these forecasts. Momentum profits are also associated with several characteristics not typically associated with priced risk in standard models of expected returns. For example, Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996) show that return momentum coexists with earnings momentum. Lee and Swaminathan (2000) document that momentum is more prevalent in stocks with high turnover. Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000) show that small firms with low analyst coverage have more momentum. Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) demonstrate that industry momentum is large. Grinblatt and Moskowitz (2004) present evidence that momentum is more prevalent for small firms with few institutional owners, growth firms, and firms with high volume. Jegadeesh and Titman (2001) show that US. momentum returns quickly dissipate after the investment period, a finding difficult to reconcile with standard notions of priced financial risk. Lewellen (2002) shows that behavioral models based on firm-specific returns cannot explain a significant component of momentum. Momentum shows up in stocks and many types of portfolios, suggesting that momentum cannot be attributed solely to firm-specific returns. He suggests that a coherent story should explain why momentum shows up in, say, individual stocks and size quintiles, but vanishes at the market level. Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003) study the relation between stock returns and macro-economic risk through the use of the unconditional approach of Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986) and examine if the conditional macroeconomic risk argument of Chordia and Shivakumar (2002) is robust. Their evidence shows that 80 international momentum profits extinguish slowly, as predicted by many risk-based explanations, or reverse sign completely, consistent with several behavioral explanations. In this sense, our study confirms and complements the findings of Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003). They argue that macroeconomic risks cannot explain momentum profits whereas we demonstrate that firm-specific risk mainly drives the profitability of momentum strategies. Moreover, we show that exploitability of momentum profits depends on certain market characteristics such as investor sophistication and earnings management. These factors need to be related to factors controlled in Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003). 2.3 Model In this section, we present a simple model that shows the relation between the idiosyncratic risk of individual stocks and momentum profitability. We choose to focus on the effect of idiosyncratic risk on momentum profitability because of the previous empirical evidence that suggests macroeconomic risk cannot account for momentum profitability. Similar models have been offered by Lo and MacKinlay (1990), Jegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2002) and Chen and Hong (2002). Our main objective in this setup is to demonstrate that in a simple economy where systematic risk cannot account for the expected returns by design, idiosyncratic risk can drive momentum profitability. Consider a one-factor world in which the only source of momentum is investor under- reaction to shocks. Assume there are N stocks each with the following one-factor SITUCIUI'CI 81 ft = ,0]; +613: rig : tut + fli/t + air (1) where e, is a mean-zero, serially uncorrelated shock to the factor f, and 81)! is a mean-zero, positively serially correlated idiosyncratic shock with variance 0”, and E[8,-,,, 8,3,4] = 2 08. The unconditional varlance of factor f, 18 0' f. The parameter p 15 the serial correlation of the factor. All other correlations are assumed to be zero. Also, for simplicity, assume that every asset has the same mean and beta, [1,- : ,u and fli=fl=1. The only source of momentum in this setting is the positive serial autocorrelation of the idiosyncratic shock, which one can think of as due to some under reaction mechanism along the lines of recent behavioral models. The momentum strategy relies on buying stocks based on their returns in period t-l and holds it in period t. With this strategy, the portfolio weight assigned to stock i is 1 Wit : —(rit—1_rt—1) N (2) where 82 1N n=— r- i,t N=i 1 is the equally weighted index return. Note that if a return is less than the equally weighted return, then its weight will be a negative number indicating a short position. The time t profit of this momentum strategy at time t is N 7ft : 2 jWiJriJ . t=l Given the one-factor structure in equation (1), the momentum strategy in equation (2) is given by the weights of each asset of N—l l N Wl,l = N2 8i,t-I ——N—2.Zgj9t-l , (3) 13¢] Therefore, the momentum profit in equation (3) is simply N N —1 8 1 N 7: = z __ ...—2.9. r. t 2 i, ,_1 2 , t—l 1,: 1:1 N N j¢i The expected momentum profit is Em.) = 1,510: There are two properties of these results. First, by construction, expected momentum profits only depend on the positive autocovariance of the idiosyncratic shocks since the unconditional means and stock betas are assumed to be identical. Second, as idiosyncratic shocks increase, expected momentum profits increase. In the following section, we focus on this relationship between expected momentum returns and idiosyncratic risk. 2.4 Empirical Setup 2.4.1 Data In this section, we describe our sample selection procedure and calculations. We used data from 31 countries. US. monthly stock return data include common shares of all NYSE, Amex and NASDAQ listed firms available from CRSP between January 1965 and December 2000.2 In order to mitigate from possible microstructure effects, we eliminated observations if stock price is less than $5. For non-US. data, we follow Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2003) and select countries from TSF Datastream International which have at least 50 stocks after Janauary 1982. This yielded an additional 30 countries. 3 Table 2.1 displays sample starting dates for each country and some market statistics. The sample of non-US data ends in December 2003. We also eliminated real estate trusts and investment companies from our international sample. We did not employ any price- 2 ADRs, SBIs, certificates, REITs, closed-end funds, companies incorporated outside the US, and Americus Trust Components are excluded from the sample to maintain consistency with the existing momentum literature. 3 Some countries (Egypt, Argentina, Brazil, Peru, China, Taiwan, Thailand) are excluded from our sample due to lack of data on reliable risk free rate note. 84 related filtering for non-US data.4 Table 2.1 also reports the number of firms available at the beginning of 1982 (or the first available month for countries when they are included in the sample). Our sample contains all of the major markets (US, UK, Canada, France, Germany and Japan) and some of the emerging markets that have enough data to calculate momentum profits. 2.4.2 Variables Returns to the momentum strategy In order to calculate the returns to the momentum strategy, we employed the procedure used in previous studies. Any momentum strategy consists of a ranking period over which winners and losers are determined, and an investment period over which winners are held and losers sold short. We use an N-month ranking and investment period (N=3,6,9 and 12) and created portfolios with equal weights. This investment rule is followed every month. Our international strategies examine the top (winner) and bottom (loser) 20 percent of stock returns as some countries do not have enough stocks to allow for use of the more common top and bottom decil‘e classification. For the US, we use the top and bottom 10 percent of stock returns.5 To avoid microstructure distortions, we skip a month between portfolio ranking and investment periods. Thus, for each month t, the portfolio (Winner 4 Ince and Porter (2004) discuss the reliability of Thomson Datastream individual equity return data. In this study, we followed their suggestions about data cleaning procedures. We also excluded monthly returns above 500% and less than -99% since such observations are unlikely unless there is a recording error. Our results are not sensitive to such filtering procedures. 5 Using the top and bottom 20% in the US. does not materially alter the results. 85 minus Loser (WML)) held during the investment period months t to t+(N-1), is determined by performance over the ranking period, months t—(N+ I) to t - 2. We denote such a strategy by “N/l/N”. Table 2.2 presents the sample statistics of cumulative momentum profits for the corresponding investment period in 31 countries.‘5 A close inspection of Table 2.2 reveals two important patterns that we exploit in later parts of the study. First of all, momentum strategies are profitable in most of the major markets, such as Australia, Belgium, Canada, Demnark, Finland, France, Spain, Sweden, Germany, UK and US, whereas it is rarely profitable in emerging countries. Second, 3/1/3 and 6/1/6 strategies seem to produce the highest cumulative profits in some countries. However, this pattern disappears as we increase the ranking and investment periods. These reversals in winners and losers suggest that the profitability of momentum strategies may be due to overreaction induced positive feedback strategies of DeLong, Shleifer, Summer, and Waldman (1990). It is important to note that some countries (such as Japan, Korea, Philippines, Portugal, and Turkey) never present momentum profitability in any ranking or investment periods. In order to test our hypotheses, measures for asset price comovement, investor sophistication, earnings management severeness, and the risk of statistical arbitrage need to be defined. 6 We should note that these statistics represent the profitability of zero investment portfolios, therefore they do not represent returns. Hence, the cumulative profitability of a certain strategy may be less than -100% in extreme cases. Of course, such positions may not be attainable in financial markets due to constraints against short selling. We replicated the study after excluding such cases, the results are essentially the same, if not stronger. We choose to report the results with all the cases in order to mitigate from survival bias arguments. 86 Asset price comovement measure We follow the procedure used in Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000) to calculate a measure that captures the asset price comovement in a given market. In their study, Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000) follow French and Roll (1986) and Roll (1988), and suggest using st of regressions of the below specification to measure asset price comovement: ’33: : at + 16,-,trm,1't+ I82, i[rUS,t +efl]+8it. (4) where i is a firm index,j is a country index, I is a two-week time period index, rm, is a domestic market index, rug, is the US. market return, and e}, is the rate of change in the exchange rate per US. dollar. They include the US. stock market return in equation 4 because most economies are partially open to foreign capital. The expression rug, + e}, translates US. stock market returns into local currency units. In order to overcome thin trading problems, biweekly returns are used. Returns are compounded from daily total returns. For stock markets in the Far East, US. market returns are lagged by one day to account for time zone differences. Therefore, if the biweekly stock return in Japan used data from June 7, 1995 to June 21, 1995, the contemporaneous US. market return uses data from June 6, 1995 to June 20, 1995. When equation 4 is used for US. data, [32,,- is set to zero. A high R2 indicates a high level of asset price comovement. Morck, Yeung, and Yu (2000) show that this measure has high correlations with other comovement measures.7 R2 is shown in Table 2.3 for each country. 7 We also used other measures that are suggested in Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000), such as “% of stock moving in the same direction” and obtained similar results. 87 Investor sophistication measure For investor sophistication, we used four proxies. The first measure, education enrollment rate, shows the total enrollment in tertiary education regardless of age, expressed as a percentage of the population in the five-year age group following on from the secondary- school leaving age. The second measure, education life, shows the average education level of population, which is proxied by school life expectancy, in each country from 1988 through 1996. The other two measures we use are the number of domestic firms per capita and education expense per capita. All investor sophistication data are summarized in Table 2.3-2.8 Earnings management severeness measure For earnings management severeness, we use the aggregate earnings management severeness index of Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki (2004) who show that firms in countries with developed equity markets, dispersed ownership structures, strong investor rights, and legal enforcement engage in less earnings management. Their aggregate earnings management measure relies on four different aspects of earnings management: (1) smoothing reported operating earnings using accruals, (2) the correlation between changes in accounting accruals and operating cash flows, (3) the magnitude of accruals, 8 The existing literature on investor sophistication generally uses institutional ownership as a measure (e.g., Hand (1990), Walther (1997) and El-Gazzer (1998) and Bartov, Radhakrishnan, and Krinsky (2000)). Due to a lack of international data on this measure, we are unfortunately not able to use this measure. Some critics argue that institutional ownership data is a noisy measure of investor sophistication as institutions tend to be more passive (index) investors. 88 and (4) small loss avoidance.9 They rank countries with respect to each of these four earnings management measures, and calculate an aggregate earnings management score by averaging the country rankings. A high value in the ranking represents severeness of earnings management. A detailed discussion of this measure is provided in Table 2.9. Table 2.3 reports the rankings of counties with respect to the aggregate earnings management severeness index. Risk of momentum strategies.“ Statistical arbitrage approach To calculate the risk of momentum strategies, we followed the methodology developed in Hogan, Jarrow, Teo, and Warachka (2004) who introduce the concept of statistical arbitrage, a long horizon trading opportunity that generates a riskless profit and is designed to exploit persistent anomalies. Following their methodology, which is briefly summarized in Table 2.10, we decompose momentum profits of 31 countries into two parts: momentum profit per month (1.1) and the grth rate of volatility of momentum profits (It), and classify countries with respect to these two measures. The idea of this decomposition is similar to that of the intercept (or) test of classical asset pricing models, except decomposition of the intercept term (WML profits in our case) allows us to study its time series behavior. In this framework, momentum profit per month (11) represents the true risk free profit, provided that the volatility of the trading strategy declines fast. The decline is governed by the second parameter (k), which is the growth rate of volatility. 9 We used the first three components of the aggregate earnings management sevemess index separately and found essentially similar results. 89 Of these two measures, we focus on the second one (it), volatility growth rate of a given zero investment trading strategy, since it defines the exploitability of a given momentum strategy. A lower (higher) volatility growth rate (3.) means that the momentum portfolio’s profit is less (more) likely to be wiped out by the fluctuations in the long and short parts of the portfolio. In our sample, most 7t estimates are below 0, indicating that risks associated with particular momentum strategies are declining over time. '0 With the use of momentum profit per month (H) and exploitability risk of momentum profits (is), we can also test whether a particular momentum strategy presents any statistical arbitrage opportunity in a given country. For statistical arbitrage opportunities to be present, momentum profits per month should be greater than zero (11>0) and growth rate of volatility should be less than zero ()1<0).ll Results of the momentum strategy statistical arbitrage tests are summarized in Table 2.4 and Figure 2.2. In Figure 2.2, the third quadrants (11>0 , lt<0) show the countries that presented statistical arbitrage opportunities. For the 6/1/6 strategy, 15 countries allow statistical arbitrage. However, it and 7t estimates are statistically significant at a 10% level only for 8 countries (US, UK, Denmark, Finland, India, Italy, New Zealand and Spain). Other countries do not seem to present any statistical arbitrage opportunities. Two things should be noted. First, even though some countries present momentum profitability with respect to simple t-tests on the mean of the WML profits, they do not '0 The link between exploitability risk (71) and momentum profits depends on the specification of incremental momentum profits. Please see Table 2.10 for the specification we employed in this study. H Table 2.10 describes the estimation procedure for u and 71. 90 necessarily offer statistical arbitrage (e.g., Belgium, Switzerland). Second, as we increase the ranking and investment horizons (fi'om Figure 2.2.1 to Figure 2.2.4), the patterns change slightly, but not dramatically. What is important for our study is, the volatility growth rate of the zero investment portfolios determines most of these patterns. Therefore, the determinants of this factor may give us insights about the riskiness of momentum strategies. Other variables Risk-sharing and hedging opportunities offered by markets may be different because of many reasons. First of all, some markets may be dominated by few industries; therefore an industry related shock may force asset prices to comove more frequently than it does in other markets. Second, in order to maintain a viable market, the volume of trade must be large enough to ensure sufficient market depth and liquidity to avoid excessive price volatility. In this sense, indirect and direct transactions costs also may affect the profitability of trading strategies. In this paper, we use several measures to control for liquidity-related transactions costs. Third, uncertainty about how the legal system will treat the introduction of new securities may be a barrier for risk arbitrageurs (Allen and Gale(2001)). Consequently, issues that are linked to the legal system, such as corruption and investor protection, may matter in the exploitability of certain momentum strategies (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997, 1998, 1999, 2000, 2002)). In order to control for such effects, we employed industry concentration, the size of the market, legal origin, a corruption perception index, the relative size of the equity markets (CAP/GDP(%)), ratio of value traded to GDP (Trading), and an index of state owned 91 enterprises in the economy as our control variables. Descriptions of each of these measures and their data sources are reported in Table 2.9 and summarized in Table 2.3. Correlations between these variables are disclosed in Table 2.5. 2.4.3 Hypotheses , Tests, and Results: (1) Momentum profits and asset price comovement Our first hypothesis is that, if momentum profits are due to asset price comovement, then momentum profits should decrease in asset price comovement. Formally, we test the following specification: MOM = p, + p118 where MOM is the momentum profits with x month ranking and investment period, and R2 is the measure of asset price comovement. Hypothesis (Ho) 1: If momentum profits are due to the idiosyncratic risk of securities, then there should not be a negative relationship between asset price comovement and momentum profits; that is Br 2 0. We should note that the independent variable, R2, can be represented as a function of various country specific factors, including investor protection (Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000)), industry concentration, choice of organization (conglomerate vs. focused firms) (Campbell, Lettau, Malkiel, and Xu (2001), Gertner, Scharfstein, and Stein (1994)), and power of outside investors (Jin and Myers (2004)). We break up R2 into such factors in the next section. 92 The results in Table 2.6 show that hypothesis 1 is rejected at 5% level (one sided test) for 3/1/3 and 6/1/6 strategies. The coefficient signs for 9/1/9 and 12/1/12 are also negative as predicted; however, the coefficient estimates are statistically significant at a 10% level.12 The momentum literature mostly reports significant profits for medium term (3-6 months), therefore the decrease in the significance of the p-values for longer periods is consistent with existing research. This evidence complements the findings of Liew and Vassalou (2002) and Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2004). In their study, these authors show that momentum is not a compensation for macroeconomic risk. Consistent with the predictions of the simple model presented in Section 3 and some behavioral models in the literature (Hong and Stein (1999) and Chen and Hong (2002)), the results show a positive relation with idiosyncratic risk. Our findings also support the conjectures of Hong, Lim and Stein (1998), who find that momentum profitability declines with firm size and analyst coverage. In other words, they argue that firm-specific information, especially negative information, diffuses gradually across investing public, and small firms and low analyst coverage are the factors capture the information dissemination process. The consistency of our results and the behavioral models should not be overemphasized. Because, as we will demonstrate, if asset prices are more informative when idiosyncratic risk is higher, then momentum profits may have rational components that can be explained by risk measures based on idiosyncratic risk. Using these results, at this stage ‘2 We employed both Newey-West and White heteroscedasticity robust standard errors to test our hypothesis. Results are essentially the same. The tables report White heteroscedasticity robust p-values. 93 we can only conjecture that R2 captures some of these factors. In the next section, we disentangle the comovement measure to test for the determinants of momentum profitability (or lack of thereof) and get a deeper look at the validity of such behavioral models’ predictions. (2) Determinants of momentum profitability If momentum profits present systematic differences across countries with respect to idiosyncratic risk, then we may find the determinants of momentum profits by investigating the attributes of economies that lead to idiosyncratic risk. In this section, we test two different but related hypotheses. The intent of these two hypotheses is to assess the effectiveness of the information flow from companies to the investment audience. In a perfect market, managers reveal firm-specific information to the market instantaneously, and the investors instantaneously capitalize this information in stock prices. Any distortion of this process affects the informativeness of stock prices and trading strategies. We break up distortions to information flow into two parts: (1) distortions due to the ability of the investment audience to comprehend the value of firm-specific information and, (2) information flow distortions due to managers’ activities, such as earnings management practices. Obviously, these two types of distortions need not be independent of each other.13 However, the combined effects of these two factors define ‘3 For instance, proponents of earnings management argue that information distortion via earnings smoothing helps investors evaluate companies in a less volatile environment. This does not necessarily imply that investors base their decisions on wrong information, but less informative earnings, provided that they know that managers are allowed to engage in such activities. In fact, investors in certain markets, such as Germany, know that companies smooth their earnings legally. In short, the market for firm-specific information is determined by suppliers of information (managers) and the demand of information users (investors) under several frictions. In this paper, we are only concerned 94 the efficiency of information flow from companies to investors, and therefore determine a given market’s information (intelligence) environment. Nevertheless, the important issue for our case is that any distortion to information flow can influence on the profitability of momentum strategies. First, we investigate the effect of investor sophistication. Our hypothesis is that in economies that are dominated by sophisticated investors, firm-specific information can be incorporated into asset prices easily and quickly and such economies should present less asset price comovement. Therefore, there should be a positive relation between momentum profits and investor sophistication. The foundation of this idea goes back to Grossman (1980), who argues that the existence of informed traders (sophisticated investors) ensures correctly priced securities, so that firm-specific information is more likely to be incorporated into prices in such economies. Roll (1988) also has similar predictions, that higher firm-specific return variation as a fraction of total variation signals more informed stock prices. Because high stock price synchronicity represents a failure to incorporate firm-specific information into market prices, as discussed in Morck, Yeung and Yu (2000) and Durnev, Morck, Yeung, and Zarowin (2003), momentum profits should be more pronounced in markets where firm- specific information can be incorporated into prices. On the other hand, if firm-specific information drives momentum profitability and this information diffuses gradually across the investing public as in Hong, Lim and Stein with certain attributes of markets that may help us evaluate the effectiveness of information flow, namely investor sophistication and earnings management. 95 (1998) and Hong and Stein (1999), then there should be a positive medium-term autocorrelation in stock returns that are owned by less sophisticated investor groups. This type of “underreaction” based behavioral model assumes that prices adjust slowly to news. Therefore, momentum profits should be decreasing in investor sophistication. The key underlying assumption of this competing hypothesis is that, in economies dominated by sophisticated investors, information is disseminated immediately rather than gradually. Second, we test if earnings management, information flow distortions due to managers’ activities, is related to the profitability of momentum strategies. A number of studies in the momentum literature argue that profitability of momentum strategies should be due to the component of medium-horizon returns that is related to earnings-relevant news; therefore, momentum strategies should not be profitable after accounting for past innovations in earnings and earnings forecasts (Bernard and Thomas (1990), Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996)). Use of international data gives us an opportunity to test the validity of such arguments. If momentum is due to market underreaction due to earnings related information, then countries that have severe earnings management practices should not present momentum profitability because investors can easily forecast the future direction of returns by using past earnings. We summarize the above conjectures in the following specification and hypotheses: MOM = ,60 + ,BllnvestorSophistication + ,BzEarningMan , where MOM represents the profits to the WML portfolio for x month ranking and investment period, InvestorSophistication represents one of the four proxies we described 96 in Section 2.4.2, and EarningMan represents the severeness of earnings management practices as described in Table 2.9. Hypothesis (Ho) 2: Assume that momentum profits are more pronounced in markets with low asset price comovement. Firm specific information cannot be incorporated into asset prices easily and quickly in economics that are not dominated by sophisticated investors; therefore such markets allow more asset price comovement. Consequently, there should not be a positive relation between momentum profits and investor sophistication (i.e., Br S 0). Hypothesis (Ho) 3: Assume that earnings surprises are less likely to occur in markets with severe earnings management practices. In that case, if momentum profits are caused by under-reaction to earnings related information (earnings surprises), then there should not be a positive relationship between momentum profits and earnings management severeness (i.e., Bz S. 0).'4 As discussed before, markets may portray different characteristics and these characteristics may affect the results. For example, some countries are more concentrated ‘4 We should note that hypothesis 3 is based on the assumption that earnings surprises are less likely to occur in markets with a severe earnings management environment. We are not aware of any study that contradicts this assumption. Of course, the validity of this assumption is based on the continuation of earnings management; if companies are likely to smooth their earnings indefinitely, which means truth will never reach the market and earnings surprises are less likely to occur, then investors may be reluctant to take positions by using the difference between their expected earnings and realized smoothed earnings. 97 in certain industries than others; therefore a shock to these industries may comove the asset prices. We use the Herfindahl index to control for industry concentration. Market size, transactions costs and liquidity also effect the execution of momentum strategies. We use three proxies to capture such effects: (1) the relative size of the equity market (CAP/GDP), (2) the ratio of value traded to GDP (Trading), (3) the per capita number of domestic firms listed in an exchange (Domestic). Factors such as an economy’s legal origin and corruption index capture certain market characteristics related to investor protection, and information dissemination process of firms is closely related to investor protection (Jin and Myers (2004)). In order to isolate the effects of investor protection, we use origin of law (LAW), corruption, and an index for state-owned enterprises (SEO). Table 2.9 and Table 2.3 discloses a detailed description and values of these variables.ls After controlling for these factors, we formally test the below specification: MOM = ,60 + ,6, LA W + flzCorruption + ,B3Herfindahl + ,B4CAP / GDP +fl5Trading + ,BéEarningMan + ,6,SOE + flsEduEn + ,B9Edusze + ,BmDomestic ’5 We assume that the variables we use to control for investor protection implicitly control for outside shareholder rights. Recent research shows that better legal protection of outside shareholders is associated with more valuable stock markets (La Porta, Lopez- de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997)), a higher number of listed firms (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997), larger listed firms in terms of their sales or assets (Kumar, Rajan, and Zingales (1999)), higher valuation of listed fmns relative to their assets (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (2002)), greater dividend payouts (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (2000)) and lower concentration of ownership and control (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1999)). 98 In this specification, we are interested in the coefficients of EduEn ([33), EduLife ([39), Domestic ([310) and EarningsMan (136). In Table 2.7.1 to Table 2.7.4, we examine the cross-sectional determinants of various momentum strategies. Hypothesis 3 is rejected at a 5% level for the 3/1/3, 6/1/6 and 9/1/9 strategies, suggesting that the profitability of momentum strategies is not due to the component of medium- horizon returns that is related to earnings-related news. This finding is not consistent with the findings of Chan, Jegadeesh, and Lakonishok (1996)), who show that, in the US, past return and earnings surprise predict large drifts in future returns after controlling one another. In other words, momentum is not created by market underreaction due to earnings-related information. Had it been related to earnings surprises, countries with severe earnings management practices would not have presented momentum profitability. One possible explanation for this finding is that, in countries that have severe earnings management practices, investors’ can predict the future returns better because earnings smoothing will help stock returns to present positive autocorrelations. Overall, the results in Table 2.7 suggest that hypothesis 2 is rejected at 1% in medium- term momentum strategies, i.e., 3/1/3 and 6/1/6 WMLs. However, the effect of investor sophistication is positive but statistically insignificant for longer ranking and investment periods. ‘6 ‘6 The results are robust to all proxies used for investor sophistication and earnings management severeness index constituents. For instance, in Table 7-5, we used “principal component of private enforcement and anti-director rights” measure of La Porta, Lopez- de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1999) as a control variable in the 6/1/6 WML 99 These findings support the notion that when sophisticated investors’ trades incorporate firm-specific information into stock prices, asset prices comove less. Therefore, momentum strategies become profitable. However, predictions of “prices adjust too slowly to news” type behavioral models, such as Hong and Stein (1999) and Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyan (1998), are not supported by these results. Moreover, the dependence of momentum profitability on investment horizon indicates that firm-specific information is more likely to be incorporated in short- to medium-term rather than longer horizons. If positive feedback traders are less likely to exist in markets with more sophisticated investors, then this finding is also inconsistent with the positive feedback trader model of DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldman (1990). In their study, authors argue that prices initially overreact to news about fundamentals, than overreact further for a period of time. Finally, although the correlation between earnings management severeness and investor sophistication is strongly negative (045), their combined effect on momentum profits is positive for all momentum strategies. Furthermore, a combination of these two factors explains about 40% of the cross-sectional variation in momentum profitability across countries. We believe that these findings are thought-provoking for three reasons. First, we know that momentum is not related to systematic risk or the risk factors of Fama and French regression. The correlation between earnings management and investor protection is negative (-0.50); therefore, when we test the relationship between earnings management and momentum strategies, we excluded the “investor protection” variable in order to mitigate possible multicollinearity problems. 100 (1993) (see also Liew and Vassalou (2002), Griffin, Ji, and Martin (2004), and F ama and French (1996)). Second, we established that idiosyncratic risk is positively related to momentum profitability in hypothesis 1, a finding that is compatible with predictions of some behavioral models of momentum mentioned above. Third, neither “underreaction to news” nor “continuing overreaction to news” types of behavioral models explain the relationship between momentum profitability and investor sophistication. In sum, existing behavioral models fall short in explaining the three observations we summarized above. On the other hand, our second hypothesis posits a link between a relationship between momentum profits and firm specific risk based on immediate information incorporation, and is capable to explain the crossectional differences of momentum profits across countries. Up to this point, we only analyzed the returns to momentum strategies and have not commented on the riskiness of such strategies. In the next section, we will revisit this issue and investigate the relation between the risk of momentum strategies and investor sophistication. (3 ) Risk of momentum strategies Rational expectation models of momentum argue that momentum profits have a risk- based explanation. Examples of this approach include Conrad and Kaul (1998) and Johnson (2002). Since we have already established a positive link between investor sophistication and momentum profitability, that is inconsistent with some behavioral models, the next logical step is to test the relation between the risk of momentum strategies and investor sophistication. 101 In contrast to previous studies of rational momentum effects, our main focus is the exploitability of momentum strategies, rather than cross-sectional differences in the expected returns as in Conrad and Kaul (1998) or growth rate risk as in Johnson (2002). Our argument is as follows. Competitive momentum traders accumulate firm-specific information until the marginal cost of gathering an additional unit of information exceeds its risk-adjusted marginal return. In such an environment, the exploitability of such strategies constitutes the major risk of momentum strategies. Therefore, assuming that investor sophistication is a proxy for the intensity of competitive risk arbitrage activities, momentum strategies should be less likely to be exploitable in markets dominated by sophisticated investors. In other words, exploitability risk is the price of momentum profitability. It is important to emphasize that we built on the notion that the greater the number of the sophisticated investors, the more they influence the stock price, because they are expected to quickly correct the mispricing that arises from the trades of unsophisticated investors. We employ the statistical arbitrage framework of Hogan, Jarrow, Teo, and Warachka (2004) to estimate the exploitability risk of momentum strategies. As discussed in Section 4.2, we decompose momentum profits of the 31 counties into two parts: momentum profit per month (u) and growth rate of volatility of momentum profits . (it), i.e., exploitability risk of momentum strategies. A high volatility growth rate (X) means that a given WML’s profit is more likely to be wiped out because of the increases in volatility; therefore the exploitability risk of such a strategy is high. On the contrary, a low volatility 102 growth rate (It) means that a given WML’s profit is less likely to be wiped out; hence exploitabi lity risk of such strategy is low.17 To isolate the effects of country-specific characteristics, we control for industry concentration, size, liquidity, origin of law (LAW) and corruption. Motivations for these COHtI‘OI variables were explained in the previous section.'8 Form ally, we test the below specification: ”1.1/0M = :80 + ,6, LA W + ,BZCorruption + ,83Herfina'ahl +fl4CAP / GDP + ,BSTrading + flGDomestic + ,67EduEn Where )1 represents the growth rate of volatility, i.e. exploitability risk, which is estimated by using the methodology described in Table 2.10 and reported in Table 4. We state the above arguments in the following hypothesis: Hypothesis (Ho) 4: If momentum profits are not explained by the exploitability risk, then there should not be a positive relationship between investor sophistication and the exploitability risk of momentum strategies, i.e., B75 0. Results are reported in Table 2.8. Consistent with the risk explanation based momentum models, coefficient of investor sophistication is positive, i.e., hypothesis 4 is rejected, and '7 One can think of exploitability risk along the lines of Shleifer and Vishny (1997) limits of arbitrage framework. In this sense, exploitability risk is a measure of limits to arbitrage that captures the risk of a zero investment portfolio. '8 Results are not sensitive to various proxies of investor sophistication, liquidity, and investor protection. 103 statistically significant mostly at a 1% level for all momentum strategies. The coefficients of all control variables are not statistically significant for 3/1/3, 6/1/6 and 9/1/9 strategies. Combined with the results of the hypothesis 2, these results suggest that, markets with SOPhiSticated investors may offer momentum profits, however the exploitability of these DIOfitS increases in investor sophistication. In other words, exploitability risk can explain the momentum profits. Can We reconcile these findings with the prediction of behavioral models? One finding that is prevalent in US markets is that small stocks and stocks with few analysts present mOre momentum profits, consistent with the predictions of the “prices adjust too slowly to news” behavioral models of Hong and Stein (1999) and Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyan (1998). If exploitability risk is indeed the price of momentum profit as the international evidence suggests, then we should also argue that small stocks and stocks followed by few analysts should be owned by more sophisticated investors. Clearly, this argument is not warranted. However, investor sophistication is only one of the determinants of the exploitability risk that explains the cross-sectional differences of momentum profitability across countries. Other measures of limits to arbitrage, such as substitutability risk or transactions cost, a factor that comes up insignificant in our tests, may be significant in certain segments of the market.19 In this sense, our findings are compatible with evidence provided in Lesmond, Schill, and Zhou (2004), who show that '9 Transactions costs involve direct costs (such as brokerage fees, etc.) and indirect costs (such as liquidity cost). In this sense, our “trading” and “size” variables partly control for transactions costs. 104 momentum profits are not exploitable because of high transactions costs required to implement momentum strategies for small size companies in US. 2.5 C onclusion We Sth that momentum strategies are less profitable in markets where stock price SYnCl‘lI‘Qnicity is higher. Empirical evidence suggests that momentum profits are largely due to firm-specific risks, consistent with behavioral models of momentum. However, aftfil‘ controlling for investor protection, market size, liquidity and high industry COncentration, we find that factors that proxy the information flow process from COmpanies to investors (i.e., investor sophistication and earnings management) explain about 40% of the cross-sectional difference in momentum profitability. Our results suggest that the profitability of momentum strategies is not due to the Component of medium-horizon returns that is related to earnings-related news, which means that momentum is not created by market under-reaction due to earnings-related information. We conclude that in countries that have severe earnings management practices, investors can predict future returns better because earnings smoothing forces stock returns to exhibit positive autocorrelations. We also document a positive and statistically significant relation between the profitability of momentum strategies and investor sophistication. Furthermore, the relation between investor sophistication and exploitability risk is also positive, suggesting that exploitability risk is the price of momentum profitability. Overall, we conclude that our evidence is more consistent with risk-based rational expectation models than behavioral 105 models of momentum. In this sense, our results complement the findings of Lesmond, Schill, and Zhou (2004). Our findings provide new research directions. First of all, what are the other determinants 0f exploitability risk other than competition between arbitrageurs (sophisticated inVCStO rs)? The relation between other limits of arbitrage (such as substitutability risk and trans actions cost) and exploitability risk also may provide additional insight to the cross- sectional differences of momentum profitability across countries. Second, can we use map} Oitability risk as a measure of “limits to arbitrage” to provide rational expectations explanations for other persistent anomalies? And finally, and more importantly, we only POint out the explanatory power of exploitability risk without any theoretical model that Shows that exploitability risk is the price of momentum strategies. Such a model should answer why exploitability risk, probably a function of idiosyncratic risk, is systematic. Future research needs to be done in this area. 106 APPENDIX 2 TABLES AND FIGURES FOR CHAPTER 2 107 108 ~33 2 no a; ooo.ooe.§.§ 3 8on S H 133mg 00sec 2.2 $3 $2 ooo.oooimaowm am 833: 1925: _ suspense ooo.o $3 53 ooo.oooéodow; E 8on z: 132% :: sonata memo SE 25 08.03.3qu so 8on :: rwwaik 225 :3. 53 $2 ooo.oedmwdom on 883: 1933: assess 236 $3 $2 ooo.oow.o§.mw we 8853 1333:” 220 ooo.o 39o 03.0 80.03.32 E 34 8on :: Isak :: sesame sumo std 2.0.0 08.8320 a m 2 8on :2 1mg :m :: 82mg 33 moo ES 80.81939. § 8on z: .. S255 2353 3.2 .Eu 3 32... raw 3 am: 3.: 8.5.3.5 3.5 5:580 .5555 9:13—53 5:35—5:93 «av—..m:— xueum gov—38 :85 .323: «.9on .5 88 Se 3 .352 6N 29d. 5 BEBE 8a mcoumcmom .coueshomfi 8x38 0:6on .358 26% m 8 m mafifiou doom $98800 van 3% >333. 50369 “amid 82m @3282“ menu 36: mm>z new on< ..m.m.>.Z 2m mo 88% 8888 83205 8% m3 .m3 8% E85 Bow .2 898032 5 95 $388 =< .9950 some 8% 295m 05 no wfiqfiwon 2: 3 29383.. ozfltoa “ch 2t Sm 86on mo 88:3: can mount macaw Ea waEfiwon 29:8 moNtmfiasm 03$ 3:. 252585 .5625 DEED o>=EcomoQ can 8:59:80 we hog—:52 was 8:5 2:55 fin «Bah 109 wmwd 3N0 000.0 000.000.0m0.m0 w: m00N\m::1N00o 8828888 E 388568 8 . «TN/ti 8 N 3808 @058 80882: 2: 886 Eon ozomtom 05 c 5808 some Sm £23 .8283 258883: 93 8388 0:883 5253 5808 m 8% 03 .80anva 8825888 Eo>m 0% .8852 xoom we 888m. 2 8088 was QB 85 95 .m3 8m $888 xoogm mo 8083 cm C30: 80:3 88 $0885 39 05 @8888 8838; 885808 mD-:oZ .8808 826 326:8 mm 22 80839:: 2? .mozomuoa humo— 28 6:83 2: 8.8m 8 .680 8 868m 9 8:395 :83 3% 88 A3 can magmuzv @2qu 808538 was $588 8808-2 3: 03 .805 28 832 88 20: 08 80:83 £033 S>o 62th 80882: ca 85 8088888 08 832 88 80:83 533 B>o 6288 @588 a mo 3888 388% 888.822 cvm m3 3N own :06 hmmfim Nemé mund— med- mead mend- awed Efio Sfio mcmd- Nwmd- 0:6- mmmd 3N4 ommd Bod wmod Sod- 03.0 wmod ~30d. ommd “Ed 036. 336 omod mmod «mc:~-a__8:m=< 335550 08cm .3.— macum 835892 ~.N.N wish. Sum 9&6 S; .o- S _ .o Sad- wmvd wmod mmod 8235.530 $88.9 mmogoxm 465 8m 8:882 8:8me SE52 832 min H 332% 11] I; 03.0 80.0 000.0 000.0- :0; 000.0 000.0 S; 0006 30.0- 000.0 000.T NONg 000.0 000.0 000 000.0 2N0- 0NNO E 0.0- 000.0 000.0 30.0 £05 wco¥ wcom @820 0:20.50 8:80 BREE x8853 BED «0.250 ska—om «Swabs-fl 0mm 02.00“ 000.0- 000.0 000.0- 000.0 000.0- 020- V3 20.00 000.0- 30.0 000N- 000.0 $0.0 N000- 00m NON.0_ www.0- vmmd EN. T R00 000.0 000.0 00— wflmdm 000.0- mg; www.00- mwoN 0m0.0 N0m.0- 02 000.00- 000.?- 000; 000.0- 000.0 Q00 000.0 0: 3V0N0 0:; 000.0 000.0- mNmN 000.0 03.0 wmm wmm N0_ 000.0 mmmé 30.0 000.0- 000.0- mm;- 0000 wmmd 30.0 000.0- 000.0- 000T 000.0 :00 0000 T20 000.0 N000 02.0 000.0 05.0- wmm wmm w0~ 000.0 N050 2N0 000.0- 000.0- v0m.0- Lv3.0 000.0 03.0 0:0- 330- 30.0- 0000 050.0 _00.0 S _.0 000.0 000.0 20.0 000.0 000.0 0vm 0vm v: 0%.: 0N06 000.0 00m.T ~0_.T 0wm.0- 0.2.0 020 000.0 000.0- 050.0- 000.0- 00v.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 mg Exam 000.0 fimmd 30.0- 0m0 .0 N000- 000.0- 3H 30.0 03.0- 50.0 000.0- 000.0 mmod 20.0 00m 00.0.0 000.0- nm 0 .0 30.0- 00.0 000.0 0m0.0 5; 0mm 000.3 20.0 nmmd 0N0.T 30.0 000.0 :04- n0m.m- _0m.m 000.0 000.0 N000- 0v0.0 ~20- m0_ Nmm 00N.0_ 20.0 000.0 000.0- :00 03.0 20.0- ~0_.T 000.0 000.0 000.0 80.0- mmfio 000.0- 00~ 00m 000.00 03.0 000.0 000.0- 310 000.0 :00- ~50- 02wm 03%0 000.0 000.0 02.0 000.0 835.58 02 as“... wNN ENS V0m.m $5.0 00m. T 000.0 00 0.0 20.0 wmm NN0.0_ V0w.m v0.0 00 _ . T 000.0 02.0 NON.0 00m $0.2 000A 0 0 0.0 000.0- 00 _ .N ~000.0 000.0 8N 323.530 000.0 000. T 000.0 0N0. T 03.0 m 00.0- 02.0- 2830— 308530 .>oQ .30 83552 858082 50022 :32 NEE " 332% N8 223530 3 0.0 mom. T 08.0 vmm. T 00 0.0 NN0.0 20.0- $80.52 000$;va son .3 8:583 83::me E82 :82 3a ” 3825 E 823530 mmmé 03.0- 00 _ .0 000.0- V010 03.0 000 $8005— 30:38.0 Son .90 838052 825wa 5622 502 £5 " 33.2% 112 SN 2 2 O: m: EN SN 28 SN 3: 8238030 N82 63 22.2: 0de E; 83: $2. ”8.8 :5 888g 83. 33 $2- 83- 88- $3. 2.2- a? 223. 883% was 23 82 mag a; 32 $3 83 $2 .25 .3 $2- $3- $2.- 32. N83- 33. 22- $3- 83. 8:882 23 a: £2 8: a; $20 $2 83 32 88882 29c MES ES 33 20.0 god mood $3 $3 8282 33 ooo.o $5.0 sod 83 ES- 83. mmod Sod 882 83 u 3385 88 NE SN :2 SN am 03. 92 § 828888 20.2 E: 220 8.28 203 ooo.o 33 2.8.2 was. 8888 92. 8:3. 22- 2?. £2- Sac- Ed- 33 $3- 883% E 2 .0 Ed 32 Q 2 .o E _ .o a: .o 30.9 g .o 820 .25 8m 83- 22.0- :2- 32- 8:- 2%.? was- 23- $3. 88882 33 23 was $2 5.0 53 36 Ed 33 888832 ”3.0 .886 wmod 23 ooo.o- ES- 83 Rod mmod 8882 Sod :2; 23 08.0 :3. mad. Sod- 03o god 882 m3» " 3385 $3.82 BEEN >62 $522002 0252 «5332 28qu can?“ in: 0520: ~.~.N 30.; maEcZ-caflob "303550 «:80 .80 3c?!— 835832 113 mcoumtomno £8232 mw.-08530 Son— .90 8:82:22 835me 92022 :82 2:5 " 3382 3282030 $80.52 mmoczaxm Sum .20 838822 8:82me 82002 :32 Ea " 3285 838850 83 28¢ 000 V02 000 002 02 000 wmm wmm 0: 000.00 000.0 000.002 200.0 000.: 000.2 00V.V 000.0 N05V V000 000. T 000.0- 0000- 000.0- NVwN- 0V0.0- 200.2 002.2- 000.0 00V.0 00V.0 VV0.0 200.0 02.0 002.0 000.0 0NV.0 000.T 000.0- 20.0- 000.N- 0V0.T RWV- 0V0.0- V000- 000.T 000V 000.0 000.0 000.2 V2V.0 000.0 000.0 VVO.2 000.0 000.0- 000.0 002.0 000.0 20.0- 000.0- 000.0- 000.0 000.0 020.0 000.0- 000.0 000.0 000.0- 200.0- 000.0- 02 2.0 VV0.0- VON 02 V00 002 00_ 20 V00 V00 0: 000. 20 000.0 0V0.0: 000.2 VVO.: 2V.0N 000.0 000.: 0V0.02 000.0 000. T 00N.0- 000.0- 002 .N- V200- VON.0- 000.2 000.T 000.0 000.0 0NV.0 00V.0 000.0 20.0 22.0 0V0.0 00V.0 Rm. T 0V0. T 0V0.0- 000.0- V00. T 20V- 0V0.0- 000.0- 0V0.N- 00V.V 000.0 V000 020.2 0VV.0 000.0 20.0 0002 000.0 200.0 002.0 VV2 .0 000.0 0N0.0 0N0.0- 000.0 V00.0 000.0 000.0 0V0.0 000.0 000.0 0 20.0- 22.0- 0000- V2.0 200 $3.8 Z ccflmoN 262 $255062 8082 £80222 «.832 Swan—- in: 0920: 114 _NV 00N 0: 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0- VON.T 000.T 0N0.0 VN00 00V0 000.0- 00V.0- 0N_.N- N000 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0V0.0- V000 0000 V2.0- 0NV VVN N00 V3.3 N000 00V.0 NON.T 00V0- 000.T 000.0 V000 03.0 0000- _0V.0- 0V0.T 0:0 VNVO 000.0 000.0 000.0 05.0- 0000- 0N00 000.0- 0VN 00V.0 00.0- 0000 V00- 0000 0V0.0 _V00 0VN 00N.0 V000- N000 00V0- 0HVO 000.0 000.0 0VN VV0.0 ~0_.T 0000 N000- 0N00 0N00 0N00 0VN 00 H .N_ 0N0.0 000.0 000.0- VN00 000.0 0N00 0VN 000.0 000.0- 00N0 000.0- 000.0 00.0 0000 0VN 000.0 0000- 02.0 000.0- 000.0 000.0 05.0 000 0 H 0 .0 000.0 NNNO 0 00.0- 000.0 00.0 0N00 000 N00 .00 0V0.0 0V“ .0 VOV.0- 000.0 0N00 0 _0.0 00N 000.0 N00.T V0_.0 _00.T N000 0N00 :00 NVN 000.0 0VV. T NV“ .0 0V0.0- 000.0 50.0 :00- 0: 000.0_ 0NNA V000 000.0- 00N._ V000- 00.0- 000 V0000 000.0- 000.0 00V. T 0NV._ 000.0- 0000- V00 000.3 VVV. T 0VV.0 000N- N00; V000 N000- 00~ V000 0N0.N- _VNO _N0.T 00V.0 N50 000.0- NN~ 8283800 0V0.0 £8950 000.0- $08580 N~N0 .>oQ .30 H 00.0- 82552 ~ 00.0 85::me 000.0- c.2002 0N00- :32 £3 ” 3325 0N~ maogtomno 00 _ .V mag-BM 000 .0- 808530 00 _.0 .>oQ .30 00V0- 808802 00N0 838085 000.0- 5602 0 _ 0.0- :32 «Em “ 332$ 03 MD 0813- 0amto~z>>0 50030 moE< £500 5QO whommwfim Emstom $500220 52$me m: .. Gflumgflm "mom-5:560 oacm ham mun-fichnw 852—0862 0.N.N «Bah. 115 00V 0NN V00 HON0 000.0 000.0 02.0. 300- 0V0.T 05.0 00N0 0000 000.0- 0V0.0- 0N0.0- 0000 00V.0 0VV.0 N000 50.0 NON0- N000 N000 VOV0- 00V NON 000 000V 000.0 V0000 00V.0- 0N0.T 000.T 05.0 000.0 000.0 _00.0- 300- V00.V- V000 NVVO 000.N 000.0 0N_.0 000.0- 000.0 000.0 00N.0- 0NN 0_0.N 0000 VON0 00V.0- 0N0.0 000.0 V000 VON 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0- 00V.0 000.0 000.0 0NN 000.3 00_.N- 00V.0 00N.N- 000.0 0N0.0 0N0.0- VON 00N.V_ 000.N- V000 0N0.N- 000.0 V000 50.0- 0NN 000V NN00- 000.0 VOV. T 0N0.0 000.0- 0N0.0- VON 0NV.V 000.0- 00N0 V000- 000.0 000.0 000.0 0: 000.0 0_0.T 0VV.0 000.T 000.0 0V0.0 000.0- 00 00V.0 0N0.0- 00N0 000.T NV0.0 000.0 000.0 VNN 00V.0 0 000.N- 000.0 00. T 000.0 0N0.0- 0V0.0- 00N :V. _N 0 0 0.0- ~0N0 0N0. T 0N0 .0 0N0.0 000.0- 00~ 00V.N0 00N.0- 0000 N000- NV0.0 0 ~00 000.0- 00 V0003 000.0- 0V0 .0 V00- 0000 N000 000.0- NV~ 000.0 000.T V_0.0 V000- 000.N 0V0.0- _0N.0- 0V0 0H0.0_ 000.N- 000.0 000.V- 0N0.N 0N0.0 N0 0 .0- 00 0 32333.00 ~0V.V mmmotsvm 00V.0- 30858—0 0000 Son— .90 000.0- 82552 0 00 .0 8:2:wa V5.0- Swag-£2 000.0 532 «SE n 38.50 0H 0 3382030 83 32:2 Ewe- 383% Ed son .3 82- 8:832 $3 8:832 £2. $602 :3. :82 33 n 382.0 03 v5 08:3- 0828550 50250 on< 5:00 580 225030 603.50 8:30:20 553mm 0.2.5.58 02 2.5 116 H3 0. H o o o :0 «23H 28 £0 E H . o o o m3 53 0% 8H 3 o o _ o 80 02 88 8.0 S o .. o o _ 8.0 H0820 a 03 mm o o o _ 2.0 205 mg 03 E o o o _ 2.0 830 80: 8m EN 3 o o _ o 2.0 886 $8 0 0 .o 0.5 _ o o o H S 05800 88 v? E o o _ o 8.0 8:80 El 93 2 o H o o 3.0 2380 80m :10 M3 0 H o o 8.0 8830 8H 3.0 E o o H o Hwo 230 88 N; Q o o o 0 8.0 «2&0 30H as S o o H o 2.0 8:000 00¢ £0 3 o o o H 8.0 080.2 5:08 EH .8088: 20085331me 3.3100 330033180 H08 8:55 82.00320 .8009»:— AVooNv 20803 000 .0000 Z .804 8000 008800 2 000 8008000008 008800 00 300833 000 0305. 0808 80800808 $8800 $0080 .8250 0200202008 00338 2.0 308808 00: 020000000 000 0085 0000000m 820000000 02 00 08300 0020 a 8 08m: m880 260800 00 00088 20 00 00.8 00808 000 00 802802 850% 20.0.0800— .0800000 05 8 380.580 00030 80% m>>00m 0000 0000000 008800 3.80 2 00:3 Emma 00008 008 20 m>>00m 08080- 0000000 008800 8000 032 00 00080800 0 mm 00080808 08208 m>200m 0x00 0DOE88: :83 288 8888 802 .88 0.888858 0888888888 288 88 2:? a 05 8 88828 Na 98 8a 05 0o 53 28% .258 SS chzooc 8 8888883 wowfigmbfic 88 8288283 888888 038888 8 88.8080 8888808882288 3888880888 88on Mozomtom 288 805283 888 88033 888 ommbfis 83888888 888980 3283 a 2: 298% mm can 888 62008800 20 85288.8 8 08: 8 83mm 880 fit 2:. .080: 888888 88888 smoocmmum 5 3 88858 M 80.8 088% 88: 888088 088 $2638 08 B88 03 08283 .mD 888883 800% 038 8880 2: 8.8% 98 8:80 038 08 05 mwco8 sz 0:00:98 2E. 8280.88.80 0:038 BE 8832 00 8888808 m 883 so 383 0888 Ba 8888 “£888 bo>m 888880888 m mo 02898 wEEo: m 98 888880888 m 00 0288 8808888888 8.. 80.8 88888388 98 88.8080 $8858 Eoumzfim .8 2an 5 888.8002 2“ 88283 205mm .08.N 288% :8 88388828 8 3388 88838828808 sz 0o 888888 88088880 uwmbfia 888888888 288 moNEEqu 038 m5... mflwouabm 8:558:32 Qdm .88 38,—. «$53.84 Foumcfim 8.3% ~35. 121 3.8 8m0 3.0 30.0 000.0 800.0 5800. mm00 m000- m3 800 00.0 800 $00 8000 8000 N88 .0- 080.0 8000 v5 v8 .0 00.0 v8 .0 00 8 .0 08 8.0 0000 000. 8- mmm0 000.0 NA8888:. v8 .8 00. 8 v8 .0 30.0 N000 8000 0 8 N0 300 800.0 05880N883m 80.0 00.0 80.0 NV0.0 m000 8000 N30- 300 N000 8808856 N00 00.0 N00 800 8.80.0 8000 EN? 830 m000 Eamm 0m0 00.0 090 $00 08.0 0000 N30- 8300 000.0 888.8588 530m 88 8.88 8.88 88.88 888 888.0 88.88 N888 88.88- 288:5 80.8 33.0 M00 300 m000 N000 N080 080.0 800.0- Ema-Sm 3.0 00.0 N30 0000 0m00 N000 0080- m080 m000- 388888088858 3.0 00.0 3.0 30.0 NN00 N000 09.0- 883.0 m000- 8888858 3.0 00.0 3.0 .300 88:0 8000 808.0- 30m0 N000- NA85802 80.0 00.0 800 N30 0800 m000 88800- $80 0000 888888N >32 80.8 00. 8 800 $00 8000 m000 0NNO 8880.0 0000 8888828802 008 00.0 00.8 08 8.0 0Nm0 800.0 000. 8- mmn0 N000- 888882 00.8 80 30 $00 8 800 N000 8M8800. NV0.0 N000- 88888888882 main N0 80 3388:8803 AmeGVom 3:803 $58888 «Emu :E @8550 88.88.888.58 8.8.8.8 288.8 122 83¢. 83- 83 £83 Sod Sod Em 88M £3. :3- Sod Sod Sod 83 SN 53 £3 $83- 83 Bod sod sod SN :2 £3 Ewe- Rod 35 ooo.o . 53 oz 23...: mood- 83. :3 «so Sod 83 w: «as Ed 38 .o- 88.0 omod wood ooo.o SN 9.38 mac: 8% 83- 2 3 33 583 88.3 a: 885 ME; $85- $3 :3 25¢ 83 SN bass-5 03.8 :83. omod Cod Sod 83 SN 85:8 ES MES- ooo.o omod ooo.o god at 2885.8 88.8 Sod- Sod mad Sod Sod 3N fines-5 8% god- Ed wmod ooo.o Sod $8 220 $3- 53. $90 :3 ooo.o ooo.o 9m @850 32 was. mood ago god 890 SN 8395 $2 :30- 83 £3 83 Sod SN 2833. “Em-8 ES 5%: >085 52008 :88 78 @8580 458950005 03 3283030 8988 8808:8838 05 885: 8538388 ohm 85883-8. doflfimfioo 80 82>on m8 08-880 mafia: 88888808 588 288 so cams-Sm; 28H $2880.80 05 8922-8 8 0%: m8 Emma 02.8 xmc 088-8- .3380 SEE-8- 98 88303on :8 mm .2832: m 80 033m :2: $898 838 mDéo: 8.8 .x. 0m 8880 2: 38% 8:8 Xom n88 288 3888 Q8 \m 8202 Ono-8:28 28,8- .mo8800ton8 @8880 9:8 9.228 00 $8608 m and co 85mg 08.88 8m 869m .558 bo>m8 .2808 m .80 858qu wEEon a 85m E88208 m 00 cocoa 8883888 m 583 0880,8850 835808 a 88:00 m\8\m 8>808>8 088008.858 .8 0803- :8 088282 can £58588 0808mm 3888298 835:8: m2?“ ..8 883835 Can—Esm N460 935,—. 123 38-8- 38.0- 08 8.0 0m00 0000 M000- 3v mD oomN mm0.0- $00 0800 m000 N000 mvm v83 v0~0 m080- 30.0 080.0 000.0 000.0 808 588-8. 0.30 30.0- 300.0 0N0.0 N000 8000 mvm 8885583m 0N0. 8 0000. $0.0 m 80.0 8000 N000 mvm :ovoim N000 300.0- 08.0.0 300 8000 800.0 38 888m 3800 $00- 0000 380.0 0000 000.0 mvm SE< fisom 08.8- 380- 000.0 300 0000 N000- 3N 298mm8m 0000. 38.0. 808.0 VN00 8000- 8000- N08 Rwstom 030- N080- 030.0 30.0 M000 N000- 3m8 888888888 :30. 83.0- 0000 NN00 N000- N000- 38 838858 08%. 8 m0 8 .0- mm 8 .0 30.0 0000 N000 mvm $3878 wmod 38 .0- 38.0 30.0 000.0 000.0 8N8 0::88N >578 33.0 mimo- 0300 30.0 m000 N000 mvm 8888:2862 808.0 08.0- OM80 3800 N000- 0000 008 88on ~000- 380- 38 .0 mm00 N000- N000- 00m 3%.,83832 :33 :88 :88 >0ch 88:08 :88 Z 8:500 Ace—8:88:00 N.—.v.N 03.;- 124 00.0 00.0 00.0 30.0 300 800.0 mm80- 300 8000 m3 00.0 00 0 00.0 mm00 8.00.0 0000 088N0- 300 N000 v5 880 00.0 3.0 0300 N8 80 0000 000. 8- 3:0 0000 %885-8. 30 3 0 00.0 E00 N000 800.0 330 080.0 8000 wSzBEEm 8N0 080 N80 0m00 m000 800.0 0000- m800 800.0 :ouoBm 8 8.0 00.0 8 80 000.0 3000 800.0 N: .0- 380.0 800.0 8an 03.0 00.0 3.0 300 88-80 000.0 0N0.0- M080 8000- 388.38 58.0w 08.8 3.0 M80 8m00 m000 800.0 300 8800 N000 o..oammEm mm 0 000 3.0 8m00 8000 800.0 33.0- 0800 800.0- Ema—tom 3 0 00.0 30 30.0 8N00 N000 0NNO- $00 800- 8:888:78 03.0 00 0 050 30.0 $00 8000 ~30- 020 8000- 838898 3.0 00 0 30 0000 v3.0 8000 000. 8- omfim 80.0- b$302 00.0 00.0 000 $00 v8.0 m000 3W0- Nm80 V000 EEGoN 302 030 N00 00.0 30.0 3000 N000 $00 30.0 m000 8:38.832 03.0 00 0 030 38.00 38.0 000.0 000.8- Nmm0 8000- 008x02 30 00 0 0V0 N000 8 800 8000 $80. 8800 0000 «8.049238 08. 0 00.0 08.0 30.0 0800 800.0 0Nm0- v3.0 8000. «Sov— 30 8 80 3.0 30.0 800.0 800.0 30.0- 0N0.0 8000. :85. 80.0 00.0 80.0 8m00 880.0 8000 £00- 0000 800.0 >888 0N0 00.0 0N0 800.0 0800 N000 30.0. 30.0 8000 88:80: m00 00 0 m00 03.0 0N0.0 800.0 8080- 300 N000 «80:8 3.0 00 0 $0 NV0.0 080.0 800.0 380. 080.0 000.0 w:ov8 w:o8.8 8.0 00.0 $0 $00 8m00 800.0 03.0- v0m0 8000- 0880 mm 0 0N0 00.0 0800 M000 8000 0N0.0- M800 8000 8:850 em 0 00.0 0m0 03.0 0N0.0 800.0 0800- ~8080 000.0 3:88 ~00 m00 00.0 0000 N800 8000 08-80- Nm00 8000 8:88:88 00.0 00 0 00.0 88.00 000.0 000.0 0090- 300 8000 888.838 03.0 00.0 030 8080 $00 8000 000. 8- 3:8 N000- 08:80 80 0 00.0 80.0 8000 3000 800.0 380- 8m00 000.0 «9280 00. 8 00. 8 00.0 wm00 800.0 800.0 33.0 800.0 m000 8=8w8om8 N00 00.0 N00 $00 30.0 8000 $0.0- N080 000.0 E8883< Nm+8m m0 8: 3858208 Ameivum AsEVom «38:8 «Ema :8 ©2509 mo8uo8a8m 855832 08880 .88 33,8- oM~bEg< 8383885m 8.33 033. 125 v8m.8- 3880.. V000 0N0.0 M000 N000- w8m $qu 30.0- 03.0- ~m00 080.0 000.0 8000- 3mm 828:8. 030 .300. 0300 N800 0000 N000 3mm N8888 ~38 $00. 0000 mm00 m000 N000 388 88:80.: 038.8 V000- wm00 380.0 8000 N000 N2 805 m8m.8 30.0- 30.0 mm00 8000 N000 3mm m:ov8 w:o8.8 mmm.8 30.0.. 38.0 30.0 N000- 0000 m: 88:0 m3.m 0m00- mm00 N800 800.0 8000 3mm N8:880 3000 30.0- 90.0 N800 N000 N000 3mm 888,8 3m0.m $0.0- $00 0800 m000 800.0 38 8888.8 :38 0m00- Nm00 3000 N000 8000 3.8 838508 wm8.8 000.0- 38.80 0m00 N000- m000 02 088880 m30 30.0- 0800 M800 8000 000.0 3N «888:0 8m”: 88-00- m080 080.0 m000 m000 08 883cm :38 08.0- 300 m800 000.0 8000 0mm 8.1..88882188V 88m; :88 :88 >25 8:38 :88 Z @8850 3880.88.88 85:08:82 023 .88 883.885 fafifiam N.N.v.N 2.8:. 126 $3 ooo.o- mmod omod 89¢ 33 8% m: :3 Rod- Rod 83 Sod 83 :8 v5 83 89- Rod 08: ooo.o ooo.o m: 8385: 33 88.0- $90 :3 Sod mood on” 985585 22 £3. E; :3 88.0 sod on 58% :2 80.0. ES to: 80.0 88.0 a: 8% 23.0 83o- N30 Sod ooo.o 53 am 8:288 mm; 88.0- owod mmod mood sod m8 288:5 too- god. 23 :3 000.0 Sod- :2 $38: 82. RS- 23 0.8.9 Sod- mood- a 828:3: 05%. ooo.o- 88.0 wmod ooo.o Sod- 89 £3.28 N30 RS- 52 is 88.0- Sod a8 5:02 $2 28.0- 83 omod ooo.o wood m: 2338302 3: M33- 92.0 mmod 83 890 am mgafisoz 28.0 80.0- 03.0 N30 ooo.o ooo.o E8 852 63 08.0- 35.0 88¢ 53 ooo.o com 3332 88m; :88 :88 >085 :8me :88 2 88850 32882800 00.90 93:8. 127 oo.o oo.o oo.o omod wood _ood mmod- _mod mood m3 mod oo.o mod owod mood ooo.o memo- mmod _oo.o v5 3 d oo.o 2 d mood mmod ooo.o ooo._- omwd ooo.o >813... wod woo oo.o owod wood _oo.o owod- :od mood EEBEEm wm; oo._ wmd wwod .ood .ood of .o ooo.o Sod 533m wmd So nmd owod :od Sod m2 d- mmod Hood 53m oo.o oo.o oo.o wood ww_d ooo.o wad- owmd Sod- 8E< £20m _o.~ oo._ Hod mmod Sod Sod momd mood mood anamfim wwd do; wwd owod mood mood mid :od ooo.o .mwstom 3. Ed :3 33d ”oo.o 83 mod mod 83. 853.5 mod oo.o mod mo_ d Sod Sod nomd- wwod ooo.o 53$me oo.o oo.o ood mwod oomd .ood ooo. T 52 .m mood- b25.52 wwd Ed mwd mood :od mood mid- wwod ooo.o nan—moN >$2 nmd wmd o_d wood ooo.o mood wmod- omod mood €510:qu mwd oo.o who mm_.o wwmd Sod ooo._- mmod ooo.o 02on mod oo.o mod mwod w_o.o Sod momd- mwod mood- £9332 oo.o oo.o oo.o omod wood Sod 32d- wmod mood- «Bov— mnd oo.o mwd mmod mood Sod wfd- omod good. 5&2. mod oo.o mod omod wmod ooo.o wwmd- mmfio Sod bad wwd _o.o Rd Rod B So mood of d- mmod ooo.o Ego: oo.o oo.o oo.o mood omod _ood momd- Rod mood «:2: co; oo.o 3d mwod oood mood wmod- Sod mood- mqu mac: 3d oo.o 3d omod omod mood momd- god wood. 8080 oo.o oo.o oo.o wwod wood _oo.o nwfid- omod wood bazcow mod oo.o mod omod Tmod ooo.o oomd- mmfio Sod 025E nod ood _od mmod hood Sod w_ _.o- mmod mood van—En— ood oo.o oo.o mood Bod ooo.o $wd- mmod flood x3859 ood oo.o ood mfld owod _ood oood- m_ : mood- 2E0 omd oo.o omd Kod mmod Sod oowd- wmod Sod- €250 oo._ oo._ oo.o owod ooo.o _oo.o mmwd mood mood EEEom ood oo.o oo.o mmod mwod _ood wmmd- 3: .o Sod- azmbmzxw ma+ _ o mo 3 EBEfloom Anemia 2:58 «BEE «Ewmm :E bEsoU mflwownhm 8:25:52 923 ..8 33,—L muffina< Euflmrflm ~.m.w.m 93.; 128 ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- do 88M mono- ooo.o- ooo.o zoo ooo.o ooo.o mom 59: ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o SN 32 Eo ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o o: 250: ooo.o too. too ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o o: 22: N92. 32o- :oo ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- mom woovo 95: ooo.o- ooo.o- mio ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o o2 885 too ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o 2N gage ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o mom 89E SE ooo.o- ooo.o zoo ooo.o ooo.o o2 Esau ooo.o omoo- ~ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o mom fiance ooo.o ooo.o- Eo ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o N2 230 ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o Coo ooo.o ooo.o- so .825 23 ooo.o- N:.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o MR 629% ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o _oo.o- :8 £228 :33 52 ENE >25 :mEuE SEE 2 EEon mag—etch 835832 oh? ..8 mount—3m baafism m.m.w.m «EFF 129 ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o m: m: on: ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o so v5 ooo.o ooo.o- oto ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o of $29 ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o :oo ooo.o ooo.o mom Edzoéam ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o oo.o ooo.o ooo.o ma 58% om: ooo.o- ooo.o oo.o ooo.o ooo.o o2 flaw ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o :oo ooo.o ooo.o mom Snowsoom ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o omm eoomwam ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o- o: 3::vo ooo.o- ES- 23 ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- E mosoooao ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o Qoo ooo.o- ooo.o m: 5383 go ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o m8 omEoz ooo.o oo.o- goo ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o o2 ofiswaoz 32 ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o mom mofisaoz ooo.o ooo.o- oo_.o ooo.o ooo.o _oo.o E 8:82 ooo.o- ooo.o- Goo ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- woo 3E“: tam; ES .52: >0va CEBE :85 Z >5:on €35.28 Si «:5 130 omd omd oo.o omod mood .ood ooo.o oood mood m3 2d oo.o w ~ .o owod mood ooo.o momd- mmod ooo.o v5 wmd oo.o wm o wood wood ooo.o ood..- wwmd ooo.o x813. mod oo.o mo o wwod ooo.o _oo.o ommd- omod _oo.o nan—.ofiEm oo.— ood mod omod mood Sod wood wood _oo.o- 533m and mod E-d m_ _d mmod Sod ommd- mwod ooo.o- Exam mwd oo.o mwd wood wood Sod ooo.o- mwod ooo.o aoE< 520m o: oo._ Eo ooo.o ooo.o 53 so ooo.o ooo.o- 2833-0, mm; oo._ omd wmod Sod _oo.o mmmd mood oood Ema-5m mod mod mod mwod Sod mood wfd- wwod wood- mw.—53:5 wwd wod mwd _md d wood Sod oomd- wood ooo.o cadmium mod oo.o mod mmod wwmd Sod ooo. T SK; Sod- 33.52 mm._ 3.0 cm o _:.o mood mood ommd m_od mood nan—noN >52 mmd _o.o mmd wood de _oo.o mid- owod Sod mug—$502 Ed oo.o 2 .o wood wwmd Hood ooo._- omod ooo.o 02on w; mwd mod oood oood oood wood- omod mood- Emma—m2 cod oo.o oo.o omod omod Sod wwmd- ooo.o mood- «20! oo._ oo.o oo _ mmod wood Sod Gmd- omod mood- 5&3. mod oo.o oo.o owod mmod ooo.o mood- ooo.o ooo.o b8— mwd oo.o mwd Sod _mo.o _oo.o mmmd- omod Sod- EBB: oo.o oo.o oo o ooo.o :od oood momd- mwod mood SE: mm; omd oo.o _wo.o mood mood ooo.o mmod wood- wco¥ mac: oo._ oo.o oo._ mwod Sod mood 82d- wwod ooo.o- 0820 oo.o oo.o oo o owod ooo.o _oo.o wwmd- omod mood AcmEoO m_d oo.o m_ o wmod mmod Sod momd- owod Hood 855 wmd mod _md wood wood Sod wmo d- mmod ooo.o van—Em oo.o oo.o oo.o Sod Sod ooo.o w Sd- mood ooo.o x5553 omd oo.o omd mmfio momd _oo.o oood- Sod ooo.o BED oo.o oo.o oo.o wood omod Sod mmwd- owod mood- «cacao oo.o oo._ oo.o omod oood Mood mwmd mood ooo.o £3305 oo._ oo.o oo.o Edd wmod _oo.o fwd- mmod mood- 33:93 moio mo 1 AmEEoCum AoEwE-om 3:58 «BEE «Ema : E 5:500 mfiwooahm 555532 mddmfi .5.“ 33,—- mag???“ Euzmmufim ~.w.w.m uEaH 131 www.m- M: _d- m mod omod mood mood- com 3.8% 0.2m- mmod- owod mood ooo.o mood- um :33. mwd; w_od- mmod mood oood- mood hmm bu: ommd- mwod- mmod _mod mood Sod- m: dam—o: oom A owod- mwod m H od mood mood ow_ «65 omom- oflmd- mmod omod Sod- wood- 5mm wmoM wcom me. T 3 o .o- oo o d mwod Sod- mood- m3 88H0 Smd wmod- mmod odod wood wood mmm baa.80 _mm.m mmod- mwod :od Sod mood 5mm 882m ommd- mmod- wmod m 5d mood oood- Gfi 983E ommd- mmod- mmod wood Hood ooo.o omm x8850 ommd Zod- 2 To mmod ooo.o Sod owfi BED chow- mwod- mmod de Sod- wood- mmm «9280 wood owod- m _ dd omod wood wood nmm 8390mm ommm- mmod- omod Cod ooo.o mood- mmm mfibms< doom-o ES 52: >oEm 5286 58:. Z boo—:00 agar—om 8:25:82 mttmw .2... 85355 ran—85m m.w.w.m 935,—. 132 ooo.o Moo. :3 ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o oov m: ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o _oo.o mom v5 ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o m2 %£5 33 ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o Rm Bozo-aim ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o Soo ooo.o ooo.o Rm 58% mono- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o 53. E 58m ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o :oo ooo.o ooo.o RN 8:2 58m ooo.o- ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o- mom eoomwam ooo.o- ooo.o- Goo ooo.o _oo.o ooo.o- a: 335 $2. ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- z: mesoooao ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o _oo.o- ooo.o ood :smvao ooo.o ooo.o- Goo ooo.o _oo.o- ooo.o Rm :22 go. 23. ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- moo 238N302 :2 ooo.o- ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o Rm $35502 ooo.o ooo.o- ooo.o zoo ooo.o ooo.o m2 02x22 £3- 23. Roo ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- a: .2332 doom-o ES me >035 BEBE :88 Z 9580 255258 333 2...:- 133 ooo.o wood Rod wowd wwmd- wmod- mmod- mmod- owod £3 :oznosum ooo.o mmod- wood mmwd- wood wood womd- wwmd =9Em cozoaum ooo.o mo _-.o oo o d- mnmd ommd ommd- omod- mOm ooo.o mmmd- mmmd ommd ooo.o- mmwd oumoEoo ooo.o oomo- homo- ooo.o ooo.o- 22:322.. mmctzmm ooo.o ooo.o Nio- omoo 9.5.5 ooo.o wwmd- a rod- mooE 2: .8.“ £532 action-80 mm «35,—- “580358 meEom .332 cosmosmEQOm H832: 05 35858 cm: cosmosom Ea =oEm cosmos—om dogfioom m: 8 9:58 swim w 5 BE: mama 0:888 do Spas: 2: mo 0:3 owooog 05 do 80::wa @597. 360800 58288 05 E momma—8:0 3850 28m 9505 0mm .3383 0:888 88w 9 02? 8me 335 2:2 2: @505 mason:- Aosvca 388% mme .88 do uwmoaooooa a mo coswfifioamo 6x38 $52? $3 mQ0E 000mm 025 05 30:0 8050 05 000.0083 $008080 0000 0006-080 05 8000800 80803802 mwcgm 080 A005 80:00:0m .2085 8000003: 00380? 80000008000 000038 00.“ 0089-0 05‘ .0089» d 05 0008200 00 000: 08 000808080 8065000 808800 36000000008000: 00.83 008000800 05 ,8 0880000 5 (8 0008008 05 03080 NM .008? 00008000 05 3200 000308 80 00008000 .8 m030> -0 80008000 8 00 88:00 803m 0 8 008— 085 0000800 .8 00088 08 00 0000 0w000>0 08 00 88880— 03080 0000800 n8080* .m_0>0_ 8000008800 .8038 05 8000800 03 80:00:0m 080 :08m 8000000m $808000 08 8 00880080 00030 0003 030:0 0mm .2508 3000;? 000 .00802 .804 8 008.30 00 080880808 88800 00 mm08000>0m 08 03080 x008 8080w0808 mw880m 003008 0000800 30% 00 080> 00000 00008 0000 05 03080 8800; 000008 0000800 mmohw .0000 00 000080800 0 m0 8000808000 00888 030% 3b mQOE» 0508 8080808 08 8 80202 “038.000, 80080000 05 88000800 r‘ 00.0 8 03.000080 8080808 m: \m 00 0808800000 08 0008000008 00 8000080000 3200 08 .8 88000 08000800 05 300000 038 8: 0808800009 0: 000 30805 QQM .8 050.:— 8080802 find 030,—. 136 :00 :~0 ~20 ~80 030 0000 .000 2 00 ~80 080 ~000 0000- 0000 :00- 0000 0000 :00- :00 0000. ~ 300 E0 020 0:0 :3 ~30 ~80 ~20 080 0000 :00 ~25. 500 0000- 0000 R00 0000 :00 £00- 0 ~80 0000 0000 0000 ~30 0000 E0 0000 ~80 0000 :00 ~80. :00 :00- 0000 000 :00- 0000. $00- 0 0000 80 0-0 5.0 ~m~0 :2 £00 050 080 0000 :00 ~80. :00 0000- 0000 R00 0000 ~80- 200- 0 020 0000 $00 ~20 0R0 ~30 -00 0000 200 ~80 :00- ~80 SS. :00 :00- 0000 :00 83 0000- m 0000 -00 002 50 080 £00 ~30 £00 000.0 0000 0000 0000 200 0000 080 0000 2.0. ~ 800 0:0 020 E0 0:0 0:0 $00 080 $00 :00 ~80- .000 0000- 0000 0~00 0000 080- _ 8 2.3500 0.3 :28 000. 2250052 0505 000020 808;: 500.500 35'0033100 358035105 0 000 0000003 0050003 0008880 300088000 ~.b.~ 030k. 137 000.0 00~0 00 00 000.0 :00 000.0 r20 000.0 000.0 000.0 80.0 000.0- ~80 0~00 000.0 08.0 000.0. 08.0 ~80- ~ 080 0000 0~00 08.0 000.0 000.0 -00 000.0 000.0 ~90 000.0 000.0- 80.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 000.0- 08.0- 08.0- 0 000.0 v0~0 30.0 000.0 000.0 ~80 000.0 -0.0 03.0 0~v0 000.0 000.0- 000.0 000.0 000.0 ~80 08.0- 080. 000.0- 0 ~80 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 -00 ~80 00~0 ~80 ~03 000.0 000.0- 000.0 «~00 000.0 ~80 000.0- .000 2:0- 0. 000.0 08.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 ~20 00~0 00~0 0-0 03.0 ~80 80.0 ~000- 0000 08.0 000.0 000.0 ~000- 0:0- 0 ~80 20.0 ~0~0 ~80 000.0 000.0 0-0 08.0 000.0 80.0 ~80 80.0 000.0 80.0- 08.0 ~00.0- 080- ~ :00 ~80 «~00 0~00 000.0 0E0 00~0 $~0 03.0 80.0 ~80- 80.0 0~00 000.0 ~80 ~80- m: 0.0- . ~m 0000500 05 820 000 0025-0830 00.00: 08:20 28:05: 0000250 35:00 >>Suom 35:00“. 02.10.: 0 000 0000030m 0000003 8885 08088-0000Q 0: 0.8 308.0% 0:3 .00 050.5 8.080802 NEN 0308 138 or —.o mmod :Fd mvmd vnmd Nmmd ommd Nmnd ommd Now-o mood ooo.o- mood FNod ooo.o ommd: 30.0. omod mw.-.o- 5 mm rd 00.0-d mmod mood onmd vad wood hmmd vad ommd mood mood- mood mwod ooo.o oomd- Nood owod- wad- m —mp.o wwmd vnod mmmd wwmd Fovd mmod mnmd momd nmNd mood mood- mood mwod ooo.o nwmd- ooo.o ooo.o- mm—d- m word mvnd nord wwmd mmmd Nevd mmod mhmd mmvd mmNd mood mood- mood m_-o.o ooo.o wwmd- wood wood weed- c mmod mhod Nmnd mmod mmod mmNd mwvd mmvd mmmd mmmd mfiod- wood wood. mood Food Food 0220- owod ”Vt-.o.- m vad memo omod wmod mmod Nvmd omnd mnvd mmvd omod :od mood wad Food- mmod- mood mvmd- N Fm—d ommd wmod Nmmd mwmd mmmd Nmod PNvd mmNd mood mood- mood mFod ooo.o :Nd- Food wvwd- .- Nm 280800 33 =oEm mOm 000808082 9:00; QDOE><4 wO >>S Om >20... mm >><._ v.3 0 tom cozmoaum cocoaum mcham 080880000Q 0: 0:0 8000.05 033 .8 02.8.5 8.080802 m.~..~ 030B 139 000.0 000.0 00~0 ~80 000.0 000.0 ~000 ~80 00~0 ~20 000.0 800 000.0 ~000- 0000 08.0- 20.0 08.0 0000. ~ 800 080 0:0 0~00 00~0 0~00 00~0 ~80 ~0~0 ~80 000.0 000.0 000.0 ~80- 000.0 ~000- 080 :00 000.0- 0 000.0 30.0 vm~0 00~0 0000 ~30 000.0 900 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0- 80.0 ~000- 080 000.0 000.0- 0 ~30 000.0 000.0 0~00 0~00 ~000 .20 ~90 2.00 00.0 000.0 ~000 000.0 30.0- 800 000.0- :00 000.0- 80.0- 0 80.0 00:0 8~0 02.0 000.0 03.0 ~90 08.0 80.0 000.0 02.0. 000.0 000.0 000.0 08.0- ~000 0-.0- 000.0 ~000- m 0000 0~00 5:0 080 0-0 0~00 ~0~0 80.0 08.0 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 ~000- 000.0- ~80 83. ~ 0000 ~80 0:0 ~80 000.0 08.0 ~80 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 :00- 000.0 000.0. 300 ~20- _ ~0 008200 0.3 :28 0000 0025,0802 058; 0000.80 2000.-E: 8:00:00 3<-_100 35:00 35:0: 35:05 0 000 :000000m 0030003 08.80”.“ 08088-0000Q 0: 0:0 308:5 Nita“ .8 03.8.5 8580802 WEN 030,—- 140 -00 020 020 0000 020 200 200 800 50 :00 ~00 0000- .000 :00 :00 :00- 000- 0000- «~00- h :00 000 ~20 :00 0~00 080 000 900 030 :00 800 :00- :00- ~00. :00 800- :00- 000- £00- 0 200 0000 0:0 000 02 $00 020 0000 050 :00 ~00 0000- :00 000 :00 £00- 200- 800. 000- m :00 50 2:0 ~00 00~0 050 :00 ”~00 £00 0000 ~00 0000- ~000 :00 0000 £00- 200- 200 080- v 0000 $00 080 £00 £0 2~0 200 0000 E0 :3 800. 800 0000- :00 000 :00 0000- 000- ~80- m 0000 0000 v-0 0:0 .000 200 $00 0000 £00 :00 0000- :00- 000 0000 080 ~00- ~80- ~ 200 200 0000 050 0:0 :00 :00 E0 0:0 800 0000- :00 £00 :00 $00- 000- _~00- _ 2 3.8500 a: :83. M50 05:50.25: 0.0:»? 30:20 0200:: .3080... 3545 351,00 35:”: 351:: u 000 53325 032335 mwfifsu .2032.— C—ocoauchm .8003:— firsv 3:05:20qu 0: was 33.2% ch? .«0 050.5 835802 m.h.~ oEaH 141 0000 0000 020 0000 ~20 0000 800 0.00 :00 050 080- 000 ~80 9&0- ~80- ~00 0000- 0000 :00 ~80 m~m0 200 0000 090 ~30 0000 300 0000- 030 :00 0000- 050 500- 0000- 0000 200 020 :00 RS 0000 :00 00~0 $00 300 $00- mts ~80 $00- ~S0- 0~00 ~50. R00 :00 ~20 ~80 020 ~20 08.0 ~80 0:00 :00 200- 800 ~80 :00. 050- ~30- 300- 200 0000 020 0000 0:0 0000 0000 0.00 300 800- 0:0 ~80 ~000- 200- 0R0- ~m 02:0 00858 0500: 000020 ESE-E0 5002.50 22.. 00 2,5 00 35 E 22.. x: 0 000 cguaoaum .003? 000mm 020 05 3000 00050 05 0000003 00000000 0000 0000-000 05 000000000 A005 0000000m .=000m 00000008 003000> 00000003000 000055 00.0 00000070 00:- 000_0>-0 05 000000000 00 00m: 00 000000050 0000000000 000000000 00000000000080: 0003 000000030 000 00 0000000 00 .00 0000000w 05 0320 mm .000_0> 000000000 05 30.00 000300 000 00000000 00 m020> -0 .2022 00000002000 0000020 05 0000000000 zoam 000000010 000000000 0: 00 $0000 003m 0 E 000: 0800 00000000 00 000800 000 00 0000 0w000>0 0.0 00 00000w£ 03000 00000000 0000000 00000000 000% 00 00_0> 00000 00000 0000 000 03000 $00000 0000000 00000000 000% 00000 00 0000000000 0 00 0003000000 0002000 03000 0.00 0003.00 00000000000 0000000 05 00 2000000: 00000 00000000 05 03000 00000-0000 .5300 0&0— 000 0 >703 .700 0300- 00 0000000 E 300000 0030000000 th 000 0030> & .2.m 030-0 00 000000000 .0 .0 00000000 00 000000000 000- 030000 0000000000 Q3” .00 000000 0000000005 00 0000 00.30% 20 mm :0 0300000» 000000000 05 000000090 000 00 0000000 00000; 00 $0000 800000808 th 0000 0000050 30000 0000800000 00 0000 0030000 30: 0053 00000000000 30—00 05 00 0000000 000000090 05 000000 0300 m0:- 300580000Q a: 000 3000.05 000000.002 0.2% .00 :03 ~.w.~ 030,—. 142 :00 ~80 800 :00 020 0000 ~80 0~00 050 :00 «20. ~20 800 020- ~80- 800 300. m 900 900 0000 080 :80 «~00 2~0 080 0000 200 030- 00~0 ~80 030 200 0000- :00- v 0000 080 080 ~0~0 200 ~30 :00 3,00 00~0 200 030- 050 ~80 020- 200- 0000 0000- m 300 ~50 0~m0 0-0 0000 0~00 £00 0000 E~0 £00 020- 00~0 800 080- ~00- 0000- 800- ~ 9.00 ~80 ~0~0 8,0 0~00 ~80 0000 00~0 050 0:0- 200 ~80 0000- 300- 02.0- F =Oucm ~m 803000 000260 0500: 000020 22:03: 800280 35:00 25:00 35:0". 351x: 0 00m. 000000000009 0: 000 3000-05 8500.002 023 .«0 010mm m.w.~ 030,—- 143 $00 ~000 0000 020 300 00~0 0000 030 P0~0 080 R00- 30 ~80 0000- 0000- 00~0 0.00- 0 080 0000 0000 00~0 300 0000 $40 «~00 R~0 050 0000- ~0F0 ~000 00~0 ~00- 00~0- ~000- v 0~00 300 05.0 00~0 0000 0000 0000 300 ~v~0 050 0000- 020 ~000 0000- :00- 300 E00- 0 080 0000 0000 0-0 0000 0000 ~20 080 3~0 050 ~80- 00:0 ~000 0.000- 0000- 0000- ~000- ~ -00 0000 ~30 090 0000 300 0000 ~v~0 0.00 0000- 00~0 ~000 0000- 030- -00. F ..oEm I I ~m 808:8 200058 0500.; 08:20 2.0.5:: 025230 35:3 35:00 35 E 22.. x: o gum finafiauozn 0: .050 33.25 8:23:82 023 .3 x05 m.w.~ «Ea-H 144 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0060 200 0.00 ~0~0 060 500- 500 0000 0000- 080- .000 :00- 0 :00 000.. 0000 0000 00.0 3.0 ~0~0 ~000 0000 200 0000 0000- 0000 ~_~0 ~30- ~000- 0000- v :00 800 «~00 .000 $00 0v~0 0050 -00 00~0 080 050 0~00 0000 0000- 0000- 0.000 «00... 0 ~60 0000 -00 030 0000 0v~0 0:.0 0~00 00~0 050 080. 300 0000 800- 500- :00 0000- ~ 0000 0000 ~000 $00 0000 E0 :00 _0~0 050 0000- F000 0000 0000- 500- 500- _ :25 I ~m 5:803 27.058 0508.0 00956 2000.-E: 8:00:00 35:05 35:8 351E 22.. x: 0 00m 00:058-8qu 0: 1:.“ 3825 0:35:32 «its .3 30a v.m.~ 030,—- 145 Table 2.9 Data description and sources 0 Investor sophistication variables Education Enrollment: This measure shows the total enrolment in tertiary education regardless of age, expressed as a percentage of the population in the five-year age group following on from the secondary-school leaving age. Source: UNESCO Institute for statistics: http://www.uis.unesco.org Education Life This measure summarizes the average education level of investors, which is proxied by school life expectancy, in each country from 1988 through 1996. Source: UNESCO Institute for statistics: http://wwwuisunescoorg Domestic Logarithm of the average ratio of the number of domestic firms listed in a given country to its population (in millions) for the period 1996-2000. Source: La Porta, Lopez-de- Silanes, and Shleifer, (2002) Per capita education expense This measure reports the ratio of education expense allocated in GDP to total population in 2000. Source: UNESCO Institute for statistics: http://wwwuisunescoorg 0 Earnings management index Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki (2004)’s aggregate earnings management measure relies on four different aspects of earnings management: (1) smoothing reported operating earnings using accruals, (2) correlation between changes in accounting accruals and operating cash I46 flows, (3) the magnitude of accruals, and (4) small loss avoidance. Countries with respect to each of these four earnings management measures, and an aggregate earnings management score is calculated by averaging the country rankings. A high value in the ranking represents severeness of earnings management. The details of this measure is discussed in Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki (2004, p.509); Smoothing reported operating earnings using accruals Insiders can conceal changes in their firm’s economic performance using both real operating decisions and financial reporting choices. Focusing on insiders’ reporting choices, this measure captures the degree to which insiders “smooth”, i.e., reduce the variability of reported earnings by altering the accounting component of earnings, namely accruals. The measure is a country’s median ratio of the firm-level standard deviation of operating earnings divided by the firm-level standard deviation of cash flow from operations. Scaling by the cash flow from operations controls for differences in the variability of economic performance across firms. Low values of this measure indicate that, ceteris paribus, insiders exercise accounting discretion to smooth reported earnings. Smoothing and the correlation between changes in accounting accruals and operating cash flows Insiders can also use their accounting discretion to conceal economic shocks to the firm’s operating cash flow. For example, they may accelerate the reporting of future revenues or delay the reporting of current costs to hide poor current performance. Conversely, insiders underreport 147 strong current performance to create reserves for the future. In either case, accounting accruals buffer cash flow shocks and result in a negative correlation between changes in accruals and operating cash flows. A negative correlation is a natural result of accrual accounting (Dechow (1994)). However, larger magnitudes of this correlation indicate, ceteris paribus, smoothing of reported earnings that does not reflect a firm’s underlying economic performance. Consequently, the contemporaneous correlation between changes in accounting accruals and changes in operating cash flows is the second measure of earnings smoothing. Discretion in reported earnings: The magnitude of accruals Apart from dampening fluctuations in firm performance, insiders can use their reporting discretion to misstate their firm‘s economic performance. For instance, insiders can overstate reported earnings to achieve certain earnings targets or report extraordinary performance in specific instances, such as an equity issuance (Dechow and Skinner(2000)). Accordingly, this earnings management measure uses the magnitude of accruals as a proxy for the extent to which insiders exercise discretion in reporting earnings. It is computed as a country’s median of the absolute value of firms’ accruals scaled by the absolute value of firms’ cash flow from operations. The scaling controls for differences in firm size and performance. Discretion in reported earnings: Small loss avoidance Small losses are more likely to lie within the bounds of insiders’ reporting discretion. Thus, in each country, the ratio of small reported profits to 148 small reported losses reflects the extent to which insiders manage earnings to avoid reporting losses. Following Burgstahler and Dichev (1997), the ratio of “small profits” to “small losses” is computed, for each country, using after-tax earnings scaled by total assets. Small losses are defined to be in the range |'_0.0l, 0.00) and small profits are defined to be in the range [0.00, 0.01]. 0 Origin of Law UK__LAW: 1 if English legal origin. FR__LAW: 1 if French legal origin. SC_LAW: 1 if Scandinavian legal origin. GE_LAW: 1 if German legal origin. 0 Corruption Corruption Perception Index. Source: Transparency International (2000). o Investor Protection: Principal component of private enforcement and anti-director rights. Scale from O to 10. Source: La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, Vishny (1999). 0 Industry Concentration: (Herfindahl) Time-series mean of weekly industry concentration in each market. The industry concentration of each market is measured by a Herfindahl variable. For each week, Herfindahl industry concentration measure is calculated as 2 ,- MVYNDi. [Na-:2 CAR 1 , 1:1 149 where INDi is the industry concentration measure for country i, MVINDjj is the market value of industry j in country i, and CAPi is country i’s total market capitalization. The yearly market industry concentration is then approximated by the mean of weekly industry concentration values in a year. Source: Xing (2004). o CAP/GDP ("/o) The Relative Size of the Equity Market - the time-series mean of the yearly relative size of the equity market in each country from 1988 to 1997. The relative market size in a year is computed by dividing the the total market capitalization of all listed firms in a market (CAP) to the gross domestic production (GDP) of that particular country. Both CAP and GDP are from the World Development Indicator database of the World. Source: Xing (2004). 0 Trading Ratio of value traded to GDP in 1995. Source: Beck, Levine, and Loayza (2000) 0 State owned enterprises in the economy (SOE) Index of State owned enterprises in the economy. Scale from O to 10. Higher values given to countries with fewer government-owned enterprises. Source: La Porta, Lopez- de-Silanes, Shleifer, (2002). 0 Descriptive aggregate statistics on countries Stock market capitalization to GDP: Value of listed shares to GDP in 2001. Stock market total value traded to GDP: Total shares traded on the stock market exchange to GDP in 2001. Stock market turnover ratio: Ratio of the value of total shares traded to market capitalization in 2001. 150 Source: World Bank’s Financial Structure and Economic Development Database (http://www.worldbank.org/research/proiects/finstructure/database.htrn) 151 Table 2.10 Statistical Arbitrage In this table, we summarize the methodology developed in Hogan, Jarrow, Teo and Warachka (2003) that tests the existence of statistical arbitrage for a given zero investment trading strategy (such as long 18 worth of the top decile of BM stocks and short 18 worth of bottom decile of B/M). To test for statistical arbitrage, a time series of dollar denominated discounted cumulative trading profits V01), V02), . . . , Van) generated by a trading strategy are analyzed. For a given trading strategy, let AVi : V(ti) - V(ti-1) denote increments of the discounted cumulative trading profit measured at equidistant time points ti - in 2A with ti = l A. Let the discounted incremental trading profits satisfy it Avi=ui9+oizi For i=1,2,. . .,n where z, are i.i.d. N(O,1) random variables. In this case discounted cumulative trading profits generated by the trading strategy are v(tn) = :Avi ~N(,u:i6,0'2:i”) i=1 i=1 i=1 and the log likelihood function for the increments is 152 1 n 2 LogL(,u,0'2,/1,6l|Av) = —%Zlog(0'2i“) — 2 272170812, — ,uig )2 i=1 0' i=1 1 The parameters to be estimated are u, 02, it are 0. We primarily focus on the estimates of u, and it since a statistical arbitrage by definition of Hogan, Jarrow, Teo, and Warachka (2004) should have (i) Initial investment is zero (ii) Positive payoff (u) (iii) Time averaged variance converging to zero (it) A trading strategy generates a statistical arbitrage with l-a percent confidence if the following conditions are satisfied: H1: u > 0 H2 k<0 H3: 0>max(7&—‘/2,-l) In Table 2.4 and Figure l, we summarize the estimates of u, 02' for 31 countries for momentum strategies with N-month ranking and investment horizon. We employed unconditional mean estimates, i.e. 0:0, in order to compare our results with that of Hogan, Jarrow, Teo, and Warachka (2004). We obtained monthly risk free rate data from Global Finance Database (wwwglobalfindatacom). 153 >35» 0.20 I O 8:82 0 8505000 c 093. 0 20382 O m..m:w:< O as. o w xEmEcoQ I z m ooo.-":0 O __ 0065 020:3 00 £QO 0 v5 9.9.95... 0 cmumzm O O moan-E cm 5 O 9.06: 0 9900 O ...-1..-!-.-.--.-l.i!-1-.11in “. o . _ .2 1-300-.- ., .. -iE - 39:80 O _ I 9°90me O _ .mmatoa 20:55 o 62900 o W 38.2% 855832 th me 309,—. «ma-35.2 iozmufim 30 200; epqwe'r 154 as. E >33..- . 02me I 2:5 0 $352 0 850508 0 m__n=ma< O :Smimn. O {0&ch O O 0 mo 8:8“. 8 .0 ucm_mmN 302 O 055 I an: 0 v5 _ 09.3. 0 0 30.9. 09:09. ucmEE O 9.95:on Omumcmo . .25 O o 5000 o o m3 0 $0365. .mmatoa :06on O O O swam... 30850 O - Omncmtofioz newtoEEm 0 90009.5 0 0 Eagom Quad-cm 0:55:82 923 no 000:. own-53.30 Earmcfim ~40 0.50:0 Sepq‘wéfi * 155 3.2 _1 i 11 11 ll llitr- it'll! ill 1 I l- . J 1 ll: 111-ill ill-lull 1-11111 ii. i 1 ll 1 m _ _ 0 >350 O W O xmzcoz 0 O . . 8:85. 0.20 . . moEmfizom 0 USE”. M 22.. W m__m=0:< O E {06:00 O a man . mac. 0 O u o _ . O . an a v5 _ 090200. comm 0 , w. . ._ h . ,. O a 0000.. O o w. 020 O r W €05.00 0 :0 c. o 5000 o . o. 0 50.505. x 0 _ Dam—505:5” . U _ .m DEN-NON gflvz Dem-0.: . _ m3 0 020.5st O 09.958: m mosagfia o , n 583m 0 0 w m Rusted m, m 9090me O a _ _ W w £298 0 ‘ Qua—«hm 85:00:32 aha .3 008a- owah_a._< 30:03an 0.3 0.50; r.— 156 3.2 0:5 85.2. o 0 $202 0 >923: as. moEmcSom O. 0:90:05 O 0 8:9”. 0:202 0000000 023. ‘ O 06: 0000.. O . * v5. 959. $9500 30.5536 0 530in 0 £me I 0000.50.82 0 000.5“. f 00509.30 0 . .. Ill-Illiii; .1... rl- -.-! ---. . w: O 5826 996.22 mcoxmcor o 0000 ucsmmN 262 O 0 5w 0 30350 e 0032.0 5300802 SES 00 see 00.2.5.2 5000.20 0.3 200: inépqwe-I 157 BIBLIOGRAPHY REFERENCES FOR CHAPTER 2 158 BIBLIOGRAPHY Allen, Franklin Gale, Douglas, 1994. Financial Innovation and Risk Sharing (The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts). Barberis, N., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment, Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307-343. Bartov, E., S. Radhakrishnan, and I. Krinsky, 2000, Investor sophistication and patterns in stock returns after earnings announcements, Accounting Review 75, 43-63. Beck, T., R. Levine, and N. Loayza, 2000, Finance and the sources of growth, Journal of Financial Economics 58, 261-300. Berk, J. B., R. C. Green, and V. Naik, 1999, Optimal investment, growth options, and security returns, Journal of Finance 54, 1553-1607. Bernard, V. L., and J. K. Thomas, 1990, Evidence That Stock-Prices Do Not Fully Reflect the Implications of Current Earnings for Future Earnings, Journal of Accounting & Economics 13, 305-340. Burgstahler, D. C., and I. D. Dichev, 1997, Earnings, adaptation and equity value, Accounting Review 72, 187-215. Campbell, J. Y., M. Lettau, B. G. Malkiel, and Y. X. Xu, 2001, Have individual stocks become more volatile? An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk, Journal of Finance 56, 1-43. Chan, L. K. C., N. Jegadeesh, and J. Lakonishok, 1996, Momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 51,1681-1713. Chen, Joseph Hong, Harrison, 2002, Discussion of "Momentum and autocorrelation in stock returns", Review of Financial Studies 15, 565-573. Chen, N. F., R. Roll, and S. A. Ross, 1986, Economic forces and the stock market, Journal of Business 59, 383-403. 159 Chordia, T., and L. Shivakumar, 2002, Momentum, business cycle, and time-varying expected returns, Journal of Finance 57, 985-1019. Chui, A. C. W., S. Titman, and K. C. J. Wei, 2003, Intra-industry momentum: the case of REITs, Journal of Financial Markets 6, 363-387. Conrad, J ., and G. Kaul, 1998, An anatomy of trading strategies, Review of Financial Studies 11, 489-519. Daniel, K., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam, 1998, Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions, Journal of Finance 53, 1839-1885. Dechow, P. M., 1994, Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance - the role of accounting accruals, Journal of Accounting & Economics 18, 3- 42. Dechow, P. M., D. Skinner , 2000, Earnings management: reconciling the views of accounting academics, practitioners, and regulators, Accounting Horizons 14, 23 5-250. Delong, J. B., A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers, and R. J. Waldmann, 1990, Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation, Journal of Finance 45, 379- 395. Durnev, A., R. Morck, B. Yeung, and P. Zarowin, 2003, Does greater firm-specific return variation mean more or less informed stock pricing?, Journal of Accounting Research 41, 797-83 6. El-Gazzar, S. M., 1998, Predisclosure information and institutional ownership: A cross- sectional examination of market revaluations during earnings announcement periods, Accounting Review 73, 119-129. F ama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56. Fama, E. F ., and K. R. French, 1996, Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies, Journal of Finance 51, 55-84. 160 French, K. R., and R. Roll, 1986, Stock return variances - the arrival of information and the reaction of traders, Journal of Financial Economics 17, 5-26. Gertner, R. H., D. S. Scharfstein, and J. C. Stein, 1994, Internal versus external capital markets, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 1211-1230. Griffin, J. M., X. Q. Ji, and J. S. Martin, 2003, Momentum investing and business cycle risk: Evidence from pole to pole, Journal of Finance 58, 2515-2547. Grinblatt, M., and T. J. Moskowitz, 2004, Predicting stock price movements from past returns: the role of consistency and tax-loss selling, Journal of Financial Economics 71, 541-5 79. Grossman, S., 1976, Efficiency of competitive stock markets where trades have diverse information, Journal of Finance 31, 573-585. Grossman, S. J., and J. E. Stiglitz, 1980, On the impossibility ofinformationally efficient markets, American Economic Review 70, 393-408. Grundy, B. D., and J. S. Martin, 2001, Understanding the nature of the risks and the source of the rewards to momentum investing, Review of Financial Studies 14, 29-78. Hand, J. R. M., 1990, A test of the extended functional fixation hypothesis, Accounting Review 65, 740-763. Hogan, S. Jarrow, R. Teo,M. Warachka,M., 2004, Testing market efficiency using statistical arbitrage with applications to momentum and value strategies, Journal of Financial Economics Forthcoming. Hong, H., T. Lim, and J. C. Stein, 2000, Bad news travels slowly: Size, analyst coverage, and the profitability of momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 55, 265-295. Hong, H., and J. C. Stein, 1999, A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and overreaction in asset markets, Journal of Finance 54, 2143-2184. Ince, Ozgur Porter, R. Burt, 2004, Individual equity return data from Thomson Datastream: Handle with care!, University of Florida Working Paper. 161 Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling losers - Implications for stock-market efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65-91. Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 2001, Profitability of momentum strategies: An evaluation of alternative explanations, Journal of Finance 56, 699-720. Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 2002, Cross-sectional and time-series determinants of momentum returns, Review of Financial Studies 15, 143-157. Jin, Li Myers, Stewart C., 2004, R2 around the world: New theory and new tests, MIT Working Paper. Johnson, T. C ., 2002, Rational momentum effects, Journal of Finance 57, 585-608. Kumar, K., Rajan, R., Zingales, L., 1999, What determines firm size?, NBER Working Paper 7208 National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer, 1999, Corporate ownership around the world, Journal of Finance 54, 471-517. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1999, The quality of government, Journal of Law Economics & Organization 15, 222-279. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 2000, Investor protection and corporate governance, Journal of Financial Economics 58, 3-27. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 2002, Investor protection and corporate valuation, Journal of Finance 57, 1147-1170. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny, 1998, Law and finance, Journal of Political Economy 106, 1 1 13-1 155. LaPorta, R., F. LopezDeSilanes, A. Shleifer, and R. M. Vishny, 1997, Legal determinants of external finance, Journal of Finance 52, 1131-1 150. Lee, C. M. C., and B. Swaminathan, 2000, Price momentum and trading volume, Journal of Finance 55, 2017-2069. 162 Lesmond, D. A., M. J. Schill, and C. 8. Zhou, 2004, The illusory nature of momentum profits, Journal of Financial Economics 71, 349-380. Leuz, C., D. Nanda, and P. D. Wysocki, 2003, Earnings management and investor protection: an international comparison, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 505—527. Lewellen, J ., 2002, Momentum and autocorrelation in stock returns, Review of Financial Studies 15, 533-563. Liew, J ., and M. Vassalou, 2000, Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth?, Journal of Financial Economics 57, 221-245. Lo, A. W., and A. C. Mackinlay, 1990, When are contrarian profits due to stock market overreaction, Review of Financial Studies 3, 175-205. Morck, R., A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny, 1990, The stock market and investment - Is the market a sideshow, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 157-215. Morck, R., B. Yeung, and W. Yu, 2000, The information content of stock markets: why do emerging markets have synchronous stock price movements?, Journal of Financial Economics 58, 215-260. Moskowitz, T. J ., and M. Grinblatt, 1999, Do industries explain momentum?, Journal of Finance 54, 1249-1290. R011, R., 1988, R2, Journal ofFinance 43, 541-566. Rouwenhorst, K. G., 1998, International momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 53, 267-284. Rouwenhorst, K. G., 1999, Local return factors and turnover in emerging stock markets, Journal of Finance 54, 1439-1464. Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny, 1997, The limits of arbitrage, Journal of Finance 52, 35- SS. Walther, B. R., 1997, Investor sophistication and market earnings expectations, Journal of A ccounting Research 35, 157-179. 163 Xing, Xuejing, 2004, Why does stock market volatility differ across countries? Evidence from thirty seven international market, International Journal of Business 9, 83-102. 164 llllllllllllll1111111