'11—...— | ‘ J " “:4.“ u .- -.. -:- ... ~. «.. u a. .,.. .- ‘ Mn 4" '2' -I~- "a' ,.. uwun wuqvuan:'I--.~(€"§-““'\‘~"'EIEH «nun-4 em-n.......a........» ..~ L} .I' ! 5“; ~‘ ,q I .\ w . “I ‘1 » ,-,-' b7 ; i :3 " This is to certify that the dissertation entitled PUBLIC INPUTS AND THE CREDIT MARKET presented by RAJALAXMI KAMATH has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the PM) ECONOMICS degree in / W - ”W Major Professor’s Signature M Date M 5U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution . LIBRARY MlCht'gan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 c:/CI RC/DateDuep65-p. 15 PUBLIC INPUTS AND THE CREDIT MARKET By Rajalaxrni Kamath A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements For the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2004 ABSTRACT PUBLIC INPUTS AND THE CREDIT MARKET By Raj a] axmi Kamath C e u ' f‘ ntribute towards Publi inputs like infrastructur SCd collectively by Irms also C0 r e frrn 'n c ‘|' ' 'm rtant im lications red ° [he hete 0g neity among 1 S 1 an e onomy. MS has 1 PO P ucmg ' etries w ’ ‘ ' formation asymm ' ' arkets, hich are besneged b in for allocations m the credit m y ' rs. This h frms Who are the borrowers and the banks who are their lende among suc 1 . c" “35 w ' ' ' ' dit mark - . ,. - Uth and pnvate Investment Via the cre cruc1al“rr11cro link bet een p sea been explored in the first chapter of this dissertation. In a model island economy 0: on faring entrepreneurs, we trace the effect of an archetypal PUbliC 800d - a lighthous , the credit market equilibrium Of this hypothetical economy. Results indicate that the effects of the lighthouse on the credit market equilibrium not only have an impact on the Optimal level of public inputs in an economy, but they also say something about the ‘targeting' of public inputs in an asymmetrically informed world. Public goods that are targeted to the low ability may dominate those available to all types. Thus, this C hapter contributes to the debate on the precise linkages between infrastructure and economic develop ment- T‘ he second chapter explores the role Of “social infrastructure” of an economy 0n shaping i [5 business environment. Social infrastructure includes not only the physical infrastruQ ture of an economy, but also its legal framework, business regulations, sc0pe for corn“ ption and need fOr irregular payments by firms etc... It has been observed that those economies ranking high On this social infrastructure index consistently attraCt higher levels of domestic and foreign investment, as compared to economics plagued with corruption and poor social infrastructure. In a simple theoretical model that explicitly takes into account such factors, it is shown why a lender (presumably a bank) would look to these economy Wide indicators instead of firm-specific indicators to determine its lending decisions. It is concluded that in contrast to private signaling by firms in the credit market, these factors will increasingly be looked upon as ‘PUbliC' Sifinals, which improve allocational efficiency in the credit market. In the third chapter of the dissertation, the hypothesis about public inputs and its ' . . 'de effect on the credit market proposed In the two Chapters above 18 tested usmg world W1 . - ss firm-level data based on a survey carried Out by the World Bank Group (World 3‘15““: . de Envrronment Survey (WBES), 2000). We Concentrate on two sets of constraints {ace firms - financial constraints and the quality of public services, We Show that the quality of infrastructure faced by firms crucially affects the financial constraints they face ill the credit markets. Both Ordered Logit and Ordered Probit estimates Validate the that . . - - . COHCIUSion talgng care of all region spec1f1c and firm specific constraints firms f a . infrast ~ ' - Clng high mctural constraints are most likely to have high financial constraints as l- k - well' This m ’5 S eon to be stronger in the case of smaller and medium sized firms. F 0 r my Parents iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Thanks firstly to my parents, for bearing with patience - the peregrinations of my career. Thanks to my Advisor, Professor Lan)’ Martin for having the confidence in this work — at times, far exceeding my own. Thanks to my siblings, for providing the succor when most needed. Thanks to friends who were there to listen. [began this work with the spirit, “De omnibus, es dubitandum” (Of all, one must doubt) T “101’" I have succeeded- EV TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ................................................................................. vii LiSt 0f Figures ................................................................................. vul Chapter 1 Public Inputs and the credit market ....................................... l l .1 Introduction .................................................................. 15 1.2 Model .................................. . ...................................... 1.3 The Capital Market and the Separating Equilibrium .................. 10 1.3.1 Public Inputs and the Separating Equilibrium ........................... 15 1.4 Switch to a Pooling Equilibrium ........................................... l9 1-5 Switch Point and Targeting 0f Pilblic Inputs. ........................... 23 1-5- 1 Public Inputs and the Pooling Equilibrium ............................... 27 1.6 optimality Rule for Lighthouses ........................................... 29 1- 7 Conclusion ................................................................... :1 1 -A Appendix ...................................................................... 44 LB Notes to Calculations. . - ..................................................... Chapter 2 Public versus Privalte Signals in the Credit Market ..................... A25 2- 1 Introduction .................................................................. 9:3 2.2. Model ............... .. . .. .................................................... 5\ 2. 3 Capital Market Equlllbnum ................................................ ,5 2-3 - 1 Equilibrium when the banks can distinguish types. . , . . . . . . .. . . - , , 5 2-3.2 Asymmetriclnforrnation equilibrium................. ,_ .--. 56 2-4 Sociallnfrastructure and Credit Rationing............, 58 2-4.l Eifectofadecreaseintheparameter'y........... -""””"“"'-- 2-5 Conclusion ................................................... W~-.6] 2-A Appendix. . - ' ‘ 62 Chapter 3 Infrastructure and Financial Constraints — What do ‘ ‘ 64 Firms have to say? ................................................ 3, ‘1 Introduction ...... "‘67 3 _ :2 Data and Methodology ................................................... . . . 67 3 - 3 Regression Estimates ................................................... . _ 7O 3 - <4 The Infrastructure —— Finance Link ...................................... 72 3 ~ 5 Estimation over sub-samples — Characteristics versus """"""" 81 Coefficients .......................................................... 3-6 ConcluSlon ........ 88 3 ‘ ‘A Appendix ..................................................................... g”: Blbllogt‘a hy ................................................................................. 97 vi Table 1 Table 2 Table 2.1 Table 3 T able 3.1 Table 4 Table 5 Table 6 Table 7 Table 8 Table 9 Table l 0 Table 1 1 LIST OF TABLES . ' ’ d Infrastructure 2 i n Fmanmal conStTalntS an ............ 7 correlatlon betwee ...................................... Constraints ....................... 73 Ordered Probit Estimates .............................. ' . traints facing firms 4 i . fFlnanCla] cons ............... 7 sample StatlStlcs o ................................... (Probit Model) ........... 75 Ordered Logit Estimates ................................. 1 Statistics ofFinancial ConStl‘aints facing firms ...... 76 am e ............................................... (SLngt Model) .......... 11 Probability of haVing different levels of Financial .......... 79 goiritaraints (Probit Model) ........................ 11 Probability of having different levels 0f Finam‘al , . . . , 19 era .................................. ggnstraints (Lo git MOdel) ......... ffect of InfraStructure on the probability rallkings 8‘ gi‘eFemancial constraints (Probit Model)“ . . . . . . . . . . - . ffect of Infrastructure on the probability rankings 6 . . ............. TOhfeFinancial constramts (Log1t Model) Q..... ‘ ~ . .82 Finance as a constraint for firms by difficulties faced As regards Infrastructure .............................................. . ~ . .84 Ordered Logit estimates over sub-sample (infr_d = l) ............ 87 Ordered Logit estimates over sub-sample (infr_d = O) ............... 88 Predicted Probabilities ...................................................... 90 Vll Figure 1 Figure 2 Fl'gure 3 Figure 4 Figare 5 LIST OF FIGURES 14 ' t ......................... .librium in the cred” Make ts ........ 22 ting Eqm ' Contrac Separa t dominating the Separating ..... 24 . comrac ................ A Poonng ............. . ........................ 25 Targeted PUbhc Inpm ....................... ............................... 60 Pure PUblic InPUt ...... . . .......................... t re and Credit Rationing ...... Infi'astruc u viii ‘ Chapter 1 Public Inputs and the Credit Market 1 . 1 Introduction . . 1e of public goods which increase productive d mterest 1n the ro There Seems to be a renewe ternativel kno ' . capmities of private firms [71]. Such goods, a1 y W11 as znter'meQVZate pub/2'5 tion decisions f ' . ~ - ts aflcct lrlvestln 00’ 900618 or Public znpu B ad examples include public infrastructure like roads 3-11 a COllthive manner. ro . - untries and rovisio - ' k 1 1th care and educatlon 1“ many CO ’ p n or "Hem, servlceS 1i e lea - h h . t'tutes or agricultural extension centers. The macroeCOHOmic r01 t rough researc ms 1 e f 1. t Capital has been dealt extensively usmg aggregate econometric 0 Sue}: pub 1c sec or S l alysis however fails to clarify the precise “micro” linkages bEtWeen model 1], nor an‘ & [5 b1' ' puts and the nature of the production PTOCCSS- Much of the analy- provigi (311 of pu 1C 111 .. S S I“ SO i, based 011 t e 353L111 P50” 0f DBIf t’ .IllOI ' amon . i ‘ a] lIIlpllCl ly h ‘ l 1 8C 1 mathIl g l t. 11is area IS 1 participants. It is now amply clear that public interventions in an imperfectly infonned world have qualitatively different implications compared to interventions in a first-best, perfect information worldi44l- This paper therefore, plans to pursue one “micro” link Where the role of the public input is analyzed in the absence 0f perfectly informed mar- kets. It traces the effect of public inputs on private investment decisions of heterogenous entrepreneurs who have to borrow in credit markets characterized by asymmetric infor— mation. In turn, this paper also addresses a key question in public sector economics today [1?] _ In a world where asymmetric information is endemic, “What type of public pOIiCies can relax the self-selection COHStraints?” . . we Our model economy is a small: Island economy of sea-farmg entrepreneurs and . x, eddy trace the effect of an archetypal Puhllc good — a lighthouse, on the credit “,3ka . . . 090ml l1br1urr1 Of this hypothetical economy. An entrepreneurlal project in this island 60 involves entrepreneurs undertaking a sea-voyage. Entrepreneurs differ in their knoWledge 0f the hazards err—route the sea-voyage ' efficient entrepreneur S having better k nowledge about, the hazards compared to the inefficient. POtential entreprene 11 funds from the capital market in order to undertake the project Th 1 O borrow . e GHQ er credit market cannot distinguish, ex-ante, between the efficient and the in 8 1'1] the 8 Cjfin trePl‘etneurs. A lighthouse reduces the risks associated with such a Voyage a ear 1) di I‘ . 110 the D Qbability of undertaking successful entrepreneurial Projects, but it d teases 068 S . asym I'rnetric way, It points out potential hazards at sea to the entrepreneurs Undertak- lug the DbQJ-ect. Since entrepreneurs differ in their abilities, the lighthouse ben fit h fiClell t entrepreneur more than the eifiCient. The lighthouse thus in ~ , ”83be the degree of hOmQ geneity in the abilities of entrepreneurs, This key result affects the credit mark t e 2 equilibrium in this economY- The intuition behind this pal”?r is gleaned from field studies carried out in the rural Credit markets of several developing economies[47]. Information asymmetries between borrowers and institutional lenders like banks tend to be glaring in Shhh markets as formal credit institutions are still in their nascent stages. One econometric study, for examplelnl, covering eighty five districts in thirteen Indian states has shown that there exist crucial linkages between public infrastructure and the process of financial interme- djetion- Government investment in infrastructure like roads, irrigation and reglflated markets which reduced the 1' iSkS that faliners faced, also facilitated the wipe-“51°“ 0f . . . . t in commercial banks in the rural areas. This result implies that government mvestrnen . . . etween infrastructure, by reducing produCtlon risks affect the pattern of information b . in . o o {‘86 the lenders and the borrowerS~ Pllblic inpUtS, by reducmg InfOI‘Ination asymmeh the BCQnomy can thus play an important role in improVing the equilibrium in the Cledlt marke t. The credit market model we consider is characterized by inform t' a 1011 3S which are ex—ante. We essentially build on the model 0f Bester[16] Whe , re call a cat, 8.1 ytic role as a private signalling device in the credit market eQuih‘brium game Igeing played in the credit market on the lines suggested by Hellwr'g[46] - D u, . . - P011 1:110 degree of heterogeneity 1n this economy, the effect of the lighth ‘ ‘ Ollse on both separating and pooling equilibria in the credit market, will be considered T , ell - ‘ ’ ectx of a lighthouse are Summarized 111 Samuelson’s EMRS, while the ind‘ t if irec e ectS St . . I . . em fr cm the asymmetric Information in the credit market. By seDal‘etely considerin g these indirect capital market effeCtS 0f the lighthouse, we can also Say something about the ‘type’ of public goods that ShOUId be pI’OVided in an asymmetric information world. As our intuition suggests, the results of this paper consistently point out the increased benefits from a. lighthouse via the credit market. We see that public inputs, by lowering the agency costs which define a separating equilibrium in an imperfectly informed market, Shif t the second best Pareto frontier towards a more desirable pooling equilibrium. While they may not eliminate information asymmetries totally, they certainly expand the size of the information set available to the economy. This link between public and private aneSt’nent is crucial, since finanCial mtermediation is increasingly playing an irnporl’a‘nt ' - - s . t 0‘ r016 In private investment decisionb 0f most economies[40]- ThlS additional benefi ‘ oliCies a PUbllc: input in a second beSt economy should 1101? only have a bearing on X)“blic determining the optimal level of public inputs, but 3-180 0D the ‘targeting’ of suC inputs - The paper is organized as fOllows - Section 2 introduces the mod 1 I e - 11 Section 3 we discuSS the separating equilibrium in the credit mar ket. The effect f b ' ‘ 0 pm 11 the Separating equilibrium is given in SUbSGCthD 3.1. The iSSue Of th Inputs 0” 9 pool. I rlurn is dealt in fair detail in sections 4 and 5' It is seen that increas' 1mg Publ iQ goods of particular types affect existence of the separating Contra t Vision of C S - . 1 it . - 31 111 arket- Thls gives us some results on the targeting of Particular t G can y es of Dub in . f‘ ' I)” t’N . Section 6 enumerates the ban fits of a lighthouse on the economy 1 1Ilder bo h ' t th I 0 re ‘ . . glrrl Q5, separating and pooling. The necessary modifications to the Samm31 R son 1118 for the . . . Db .ov1310n of public goods are suggesmd The paper ends With sec tion 7 h , w ere We oi . . D Rt. (31% areas of further research and give the COnClllSlOIlS and some D011 cy implicat' 10113 4 of our analysis. 1.2 Model ' ' ' ‘ 3 -- ct to their Agents. WC corlsider a small island economy in Which agents differ With respc innate ability a A proportion 7 of these agents is of low ability, denoted by 0L and (1 ‘ 7) is of high ability, denoted by 011- Whether an agent is type aL or a” is private 0 o o O c ' 1 e infonnat ' Agents can take up entrepreneurial pro J ects in this economy which an0 v 1011. ‘70 te WhiCh ' a. ya. 8 Y the hazards en’rou , Sea V033_ge_ [he IISkS on SUCh g are defined by ‘ i t, agents are N in ber So ability in thls ecoIlomy corresponds to the knowledge the num . , . the“ ' ‘ er 1“ haVG abQ t the hazards on this Sea’VOYage, and the potential entrepreneurs dlfi 1.1 a 0“ . we knowledge about the hazards. These N hazards can be thought of as being. or t6 ”A a scale of visibility- The most VISIble and obvrous azar s are known to all a the less, obvious are known only to the efficient types. Agents of type a H are aware 0f M H hazards and agents of type 0L are aware Of ML hazards en route. ML V M /V fl < . Additionally, we assume (ML) C (MH) The type a” entrepreneurs are aWab hazards known to the type 0L. Q 012-111 the A 11 agents in this economy are identically endowed with one unit of labo 1" (I) o ‘ O Wh - they ‘ ' . - We assume initially that all agents are also ident' 1C}: S hpply inelastically. many with endOWQd With a physical endowmentw. We RSSUIIIG that w < l, and u) can be Used e ither for consLl 1" leti on or investment. These agents are risk neutral and live for two Derio ds. They prod 11 C6 in the first period and consume in the second period. Agents have two distinct C110ng 3, to be workers and work in a ‘TOutinc’ activity, or to be potential entrepreneurs Cf! d bark on an entrepreneurial project involving a sea voyage- M’Orkers are assumed an em 1y only and for their labor, each worker gets a deterministic return 2,. Efficient SUPP k s get a higher return denOted by ZH, as Compared to the inefficient agents who wor er get Z L. We assume, A 1 Z” > ZL. This assumption implies that efficient types dominate wrth respect to this ‘routine’ ac- tivity also and as we shall see below, this assumption is ' Important to the results in this model. ' their labor with one The potent“1 9“ rel" It of capital (k) and ° ' t. One unit of capital (1:) is . the entrepreneurial ProJeC . embark on . Vested in the prOJeC t one period ahead of time, and it fully deprec1ates after one period - f - . fp r 0duetion. Poten- tial entrepreneurs have to borrow this one unit 0 capital (1:) In 0 er to undertake the project In addition, we assume that they can only use In as “mater 8.1 to O . ' ' hi wreck, the f . Q11) ca “8, ('1’) for investment. If the prOJeCt ends in a S p- Y Orfelt t eir €011 P 1 BanS. Banks are special firms WhiCh oper ate as delegated monitor tefa]. S for '3. ' ' ' k ny’ende as deSQ ibed by Diamond [35], Banks In this economy are I‘lS —neutral and act rs r . . Betrand Com D Qt' tors in a market where they obtain elastically supplied funds. We nor 1 gross ‘1 osit rate at which the banks obtain these funds to be one. Since 813 We 388qu . fits in e uilibrium . bank§ to be Betrand competitors, they make zero PTO Q on the prolects they I 13 find. ' ts" The returns from the entrepreneurial PFOlCCtS have the f0110Wing character- \fijcc ‘ ' $ng \ they are: (a) Uncertain - A successful PFOJ ect yields y > 0, while an unsuccfissful project, which involves a ship-wreck, yields nothing. (b) The returns depend Upon the ability of the entrepreneur. Agents of type an (ell ficient) have a higher probability Of making the project a SUCCESS, as compared to the type a1, (inefficient) agents. We make a Simplifying assumption that a type an agent . A! has a success probability given by ’Nfl’ and a type aL agent has a Success probabil' t 1 Y iven b Mi. Thus the abilit of the entrepreneurs in makin a . g y N y g SnCCeSS of their PTOject is linked to their knowledge of the hazards on the sea journey, ie, M . ' ’ 7w 2 6 {H,L}. The efficient agents get higher expected returns from the project as . Compared to the ineffi- cient agents, A—fiiy > iffy. In this model, followmg DeMeza an , _ . _ Webb [28], we assume that the distribution of returns to the hlgh ablhty (low risk) bOrr . - - er GXhi its first order stochastic dominance (FOSD) over the distribution of retums t b 0 _ the 1 .. . risk) borrower} Here, the high ability types get hlgher return Ow ability (high in an - undertake. The Opportunity cost of entrepreneurship are higher f aetlvities they . . . ”10 SO: an efficient type will invest "1 the PFOJeCt only If the net returns f re efiicjent r011) ' Exceed his opportunity costs.2 e project (C) h igh yielding - We explicitly assume ‘high yielding’ to be, A 2 {H11 y — 1 > 21. The expected value of the net returns from the proje JV Ct exceed th 6 0 Eva ktu'n’ity cost of the project to all agents. 1b ' ' ' {\is is in contrast to the Stiglitz-WciSS [65] model» Where d‘Str‘bumn Of mums ‘0 the high risk is a m . . 2c 3‘ {E preserving spread of the distribution of returns to the low risk (SOSD). b is assumption is also in consonanCC With Spencc’s labor-market Signalling model, where the reset ,_ . . . ' \ ;:\_ tion wages of the high ability are higher. While 91%; - 1 are the expected 1' etUrns and 1 is the value of the l1:)01'rowed capital, this assumption implies that there exiSt incentives for all agents to undertake the project. Public goods ‘9’ in the nature of zinfnwit"‘ucture: The economy has to be provided with ‘g’, which has the characteristic Of a pure public good, in this case ' a lighthouse. It is non—rival and non—exclusive in 1158' HOW g enters into the dECision making process will be explained below. It is assumed that the level of infrastructure cgv plays a Critical role in determining the success probabilities of the project. A lighthouse points out additional hazards on the sea—route to all entrepreneurs. Since the hazards can be ranked in increasing order of their visibility - a lighthouse win typiCal y result only in two possibilities, (Athe targeted public good: a lighthouse which will brill . . '30 light one hazard known to the efficient type, but not to the IneffiClent type, 0, (B)The pure public good: a lighthouse which will bring to light on e h azard before to both types. 3 unknown In Scenario (A), We are restricting ourselves to public. gOOdS WhiCh directly . . Th 1' hthouse here directl Qnefit 0 the 10w_ability types in the economy e 1g ’ y benefits 0 my .3? the ° t a5, Si 11 06 the type a H was aware of this hazard before. J’De “21% define the effect of this lighthouse (A) as per the followrng, Vi e {11,14}, dU,‘ __ BUL ___L.dM where —LdM = 1. a d dam) ~ aMb dQM) ‘19“) nd fl“ dgp‘) : 0 SMILES“ ‘ (B) On the other hand is him general case ' public gOOdS benefit both Woes 1‘10 1 ‘ ’ ‘ ’ " ‘ ‘ " in tl). §\ onomy efficient as well as the inefficient. With the provision of the lighthouse, ‘ eC ’ ' «3" 4 and A! L increase by one in this case. We can define the effect of this lighthouse H KB\ 3kg per the following, Vi E {H, Li’ whef‘e ail/L zeta—:1. _ (9U 4M an (ill ’1‘ \L __L_ -l I (“Wu 49(3) (19(8) _——L— (19(3) BAIL (19(3) 8M” (19(3) We then have the following, P sition 1 In both scenarios, (A) and (B), the lighthouse increases the ropo h eneity in the economy ' However, this increase in the homogeneity is omog 3 higher with 9(A) as compared to 9(3)- The intuition behind this DTOPOSition is that the lighthouse affects the productivity of - '1 th (1‘ entrepreneurs in an asymmetrlC way. 80’ Whl e e fleet effect 0f the lighthouse on , . . . is obvious, we haVe to consid - . , the PTOduethlty 0f entrepreneurb er the ‘indirect effects eneity in the economy. We tr which stem from reduced heterog QQe this indirect effect - - ’derin both . t. Additionally, by conSI g t . through the Capltal mar ke h eSe Effects, the direct - ble to compare 1: e two seen , - ' ct, we Will also be a 1 . and the indire OS (A) and (B) This will basically tell us something about the «type of public goodS at: ShOUId be built - t \ . f homogeneity, then pr . . a1], Mi. 3 the degree 0 ODOS 3” We assume M" to summarlz "no" (1) Stat $3 that A!‘ . ' _ this ro erty. To take a con ‘nereasing Not all Pnblle lnPUtS may have p p Crete example . My . ’ In p "blic ' es like setting up Public research instituteS, 01‘ DFOVlding information about SeerC is}: - _ _ J’Iejd- agricu 1t. 1 techniques and inputs to farmers (both actively pursued by the Indian gOVernme mg um I" dun he head] on benefitin th the ‘EF . , . 1970’s) the focus could be SDBCI y g e most Q‘en revolution in the ’ produCtiVe making Our en: in the economy will fall. However, 1) seetorg In this case, 11%;, the degree 0f homogen y y \ ' - v ture the nature of benefits derived fr . 88511”) M - .~ ‘5 fit any hope to cap Om "‘0‘ . —J- ~ asma - we es 9. 1 st Q tion Of My mere 0 bastc i \ fr aStructure goods and services. 1.3 The capital market and the separating equilib— rium In this section we consider the Capital market Where the information asymmetry is ex. th ' - ° ' M M ante viz., the borrowers know whether 911" success probablhty ‘3 TV“ or —N11, but banks only know the average ability of the entrepreneurs applying for 108.113 The optimal lending contract: Assume there exists only a Standard debt COHtract, for investing funds (issuing equity is costly). As in the model of BeSter [16] banks offer a loan comract consisting of a pair (r,c) where 7' ‘S the gross int 1‘ est rate charged and c is the collateral that the borrowers are wrlhng to put Up- Simil . . . r to the Besanko and Thakor model [15], we make the followmg additional assumption A 3 Collateralz'zing is costly. Collateral of value Ci t0 the 5077b er . 92068 t t b value of fig, in the event the borrower defaults, where fl 6 (0, 1). 0 he ank a Note that apart from having real world justificatlon, thls asSunlption is 1 a SQ ' ' C‘r . the existence of equilibrium in a rlSk neutral enVlronment[26]. As in med Hera] for Q1 ' ' ‘ - git» [46], the a 3 stage sequentlal game IS bemg played 11} the cre di t "161 en by ”re: gam . d ‘ actions of borrowers It ' . This e prlicitly takes into account ynamlc re ‘ - 13 Played as f 11 St . _ , . , age \1 : Loan contract offer made by bankS, the uninformed player in the game, (Ti, Ci) $093 11- The informed players, the borrowers: Choose to apply for contracts they View as m '\\:;t attractive. Each borrower can apply only for a single contract. Stags: 111° The Bank may accept or reject the loan applications they have received in 8&ng II. 10 The Optimal contract (fa-fir); Vi 5": H1 L is a set of contract offers which determine the equilibrium in this 3 stage game- i.e. given (73,61) Vi = H , L - Banks make zero profits on each contract and - No bank has the incentive to offer a different loan contraCt than the ones offered. Since this game is sequential, the equilibrium considered Will be the sub—game perfect or sequential equilibrium. The usual COHdition that each agent’s Strategy be the best response to the other agents’ strategies is applied not only to the overall game, but to every decision node in the game tree, regardless 0f Whether this node is reached in equilibrium. We define Uij to be the utility to agent of type 2' 21pm)?i 11g for a loan contract meant for type j, and it is given 38: Mi 1% Ur]. N (y—m—u— WM —2; ll The problem for the bank is, Max 7ULL + (1’7)UHH sat. {rs :Ci} . Mi . Mi (1) the? Zero profit constraint for the banks: W“ + (1 — 7v— BCi = 1. 1.. _ . (1) t1” 1% self selection constraints Uii 2 U 0'- B Q fore analYZing the asymmetric information case, we solve for the perfect info rrn ‘ thn . - _ . Q ‘ -r g a benchmark. The self selection constraints do not bind this Q58 3* case. We In ' - 3 . - snark-1719 U m SUblect t0 the zero profit constraint of the banks (1), and the assumption that “Cir 4 1_ We see that [See Notes to Calculations], Ci = 0 (N0 collateral). 11 \l \ Ti 1112‘ i : {H,L}_ In the perfect information case, the interest rates charged by the banks reflect perfectly the risks (inverse of the entrepreneurial 8Lbilities) associated with the project. The low ability entrepreneur is charged a higher interest rate (TL) than the high ability type (r11). These contracts cannot be optimal in the asymmetric information case, since bOth types would prefer contracts meant for the efficient types. To see the equilibrium in the Asymmetric information case, totally differentiate U to get the slope of the indifference curves of the borrowers in th0 r‘c space, d7} N — Mi 21—- Mi 6‘ (1.1) (1) establishes both the negative slope and the single (3033ng pro ebt . - - . y of the indifference curves in the r-C space. The indifference curve Of the memment b0 1” 1‘0 . - Th efficient b Wer IS steeper (has lOWer MRS) than the effluent borrower. e orrower S 1e . on account of a ship-wreck and lose hlS collatera - 0, Of a given dec 0 efault reHSe in rate, an efficient type would be willing to DOSt more collateral then the in ejnterest e . . Qic- eXPIai 115 the reason for the higher MRS. Likerse, the expected returns to th at Q . bank 18 $th by 9,11%“ + (Ljvh’ll)fi0l Totally differentiating it we get the slope of the . (Rb) SOI‘evenu €11er . - ace e for the bank in the r c Sp , dri _ —L3(N - Mi) 222: _ M1. (1.2) 3.. \istenee Of a separating equilibrium requires: (a) b :t e isorevenue curves of the banks should be flatter than the indifference curves of ‘1 thek) Qrmwgm In this Case, assuming 13 < 1 assures us this. 12 (b) A condition on the composmion 0f the economy, where we ass ‘Jme 7 is high. This assumption - the presence of large number 0f 10w ability individ 118.18, ensures us the existence of a separating equilibrium (See Rothschild and Stigtitz [60]) For deriving the equilibrium contr act (721,61), we see that 11) does not impose a. binding constraint on collateral. For the equilibrium, the only self selection constraint which is binding is U LL _>_ U LH — the constraint which applies to the low‘ability entreprenem mimicking the high ability types.4 This is used in Solving f . or the Optlmal contracts and we get, [Proof in the Appendix], Proposition 2 " N . C :: (I c = 0 H c \ M A _ N T‘ : ~N ‘MHD TL " ML H M” +86 6' (1 \ A) . . My ' In the process of self-selection, the low-ability types get the same (:0 “tree , . . . 1: under the perfect information case, while the hlgh-abllity have t o dist- 38 they would 111g Dish by willing to pay COllateral. Collateral in this economy has a (3031;, Sine themSBIVes borrowers pay higher interest rate than the high-ability borrowers, they hav e - 1) in to m‘ 1111c as the high-ability typeS- They must therefore be deterred from the c Centive C . . . O I C Q g t Om“ act meant for the high ablllty typeS- T1118 ‘5 aCh‘eved by requmng the hi be t gh‘abuity o . _. . DQ§ t Collateral, since it IS onerous for the low—ability to post collateral. 4F . '- }\ 6 Optimal solution is obtained by COIlJeCtllrlllg at first that UHH > U H L, so that there exists only _ _ _ _ . , . .‘ . b, = _ Q ‘ixue self—selection constraint which 15 binding, 311d Wh’Ch ‘5 given 3 ULL ULH. After SOlV'lng. [or “X“ op‘imiyai ion problem we can show that the solution satisfies our conjectureisee Besanko and - 7 , . . , . T\\B.\§Q b [.15] ) 13 F' e 1 Separating Equilibrium in the Credit igur - Market r (FL, cL=o) ‘1 (TH, CH) TH BL Bu C ' ‘ shown in the Collateral sorts borrowers by type. The same lb figbq‘ I f t th : 0V8 Where in the ac (1 re ers o - , interest rate (r) and collateral (0) SP e, the H e "Rh eren Ce c are flatter than the indifference c high ability entrepreneurs. They . W ‘ . , 1‘ profit 111108 0 BH refers to the 70 t reneurs denot d by L, 0w ‘ 'brium contracts for the low-e . boerWerS (TL) CL) and (771,611) are the equill fliclency and the I‘ ‘ . es CCthEly- l 1 gh—effimency types r p abiIi ty q 'v ' the credit market, the equilibr‘m se ' ~ ' t1 e contracts in 1 If i. election of the respec the l l ’ ( t1( l‘ K‘ ' “(:11 (in; l)(,l()Uh‘ ) % 01 th(’ by" t p n‘ of ’n ' 'I) ,n(’lll , ar‘; g1 .~ 5, ’ I] A ML ’1 ULL = _N—y N - Mu) ‘ 5313/ -1-afli<1—m<(—-—N—~—)1 5 I ll 14 We see that the low ability entrepreneur ends up with a payoff eq 11a] to what, he would have got in the perfeCt informatI'On case. On the other hand the high ability 611- trepreneur’s 1333“)“ is lower to the extent 0f the signalling costs which he has to incur in the form of collateral. 1.3.1 Public inputs and the separating equilibrium Lighthouse (A) -' The targeted Public inputs We begin initially consid . - c6 lighthOUSe (A), which is directly beneficial only to the low ability types“ Sm are . e Increases M1,, the hazards known to the low-ability types. The total befi calculated as follows acted . 6 . (1) “Direct” benefits: All the low-ability entrepreneurs face an inCrease in ”b "13 T‘ms 0“ o . . . . 0‘531 returns due to alowermg of risks In the sea-voyage, given to be 116 whiCh 15 P equals the marginal benefits of the lighthouse in a perfect information world as well. (ii) “Indirect” benefits stemming from the capital market These indirect benéfits are b . a- SiCally of two types: (a) The benefits accruing from lower interest rates due t 10 . ‘ _ . . maIgl'nally Wer I'lSk of a ship-wreck. The hlgh-ablhty entrepreneurs do not get the b QIzefi t of duCCd interest rates, but they benefit from (b) lower Collateral costs wh~ re- ’ 1o . as, 18 given aUHH 86H [( N — 1W 1. ~— 1 —— [3) (‘5. 39M) aM” N )1 (1 3) We See that 3%}; < 0.[See Notes to Calculations (HH- Therefore, we get BU N111 . . d9”) > 0' Thlls by \Oworing the amount of collateral that, 18 required of the efficient tVDog 3 public #100 (ls ' 0 fi ,3 also reduce the “Slgnallmg costs . 15 This benefit of the lighthouse is peculiar to an asymmetric info 1717.52an environment, where the outcomes are pareto i“Efficient- The direct benefit of the lighthouse to the high-ability type is zerO, because he has previous knowledge of the additional hazard. However in the credit market Where the banks are unaware of types: he has to p03t collateral in order to signal his type- These Signalling costs are directly related to the degree of heterogeneity in ability. The higher the difference in the abilities of the 'm: . 1' types (2%,: is low), the higher is the cost borne by the high—ability entrepreneur m w Of COIIateral. A public good which increases the ability of the ineficlen degree of heterogeneity in the economy. The intuition is that by decreas'mg‘ 6 €06 . . I) . ‘0 heterogeneity, the lighthouse relaxes the self-selection constralnt (ULL 7 U file ‘1 o . . a . seli-selection constraint is relaxed, mimicking is no longer seen to be that 6&8 “A l“ . ‘ . f the inefficient, and the costs of Signalling to the EffiCient is r e duce d. T1115 15 the lower collateral for the efficient types. (iii) “Entry effects”: These arise in the case of the inefficient, entrepreneurs, d‘ue to lower interest rates. (ii) and (iii) are benefits of the lighthOflSe WhiCh accrue due to the inefficieh c - . . . 01¢?st the r ed1 1: market, arising from asymmetrlc Informatlon- Both these additional . . U have to be included in the Cost—Benefit analysrs of the lighthouse, and they fir St di ‘ SCUSSed “\ SeCtion 6. Lighthouse (B) - The pure public inputs Here, the lightl1011sc benefitg b ‘ . . 0th tyDos of entrepreneurs. The benefits of this lighthouse are given by, (t) “Direct” benefits to both types: Direct effects on the productivity of b th t O ypes are given by the increase in the expected returns from the projects- In the Gas f tl l e 0 1e CW. 16 ability, the eXpected returns rise by 1, which . . N IS the Same as In the Case oft/16 [get/101158 A . For the hi h-ability, his dire (3t product' ' ( ) g lvlt’y benefits (Which were 2310111 the previous case (A)), go up by the term, (716‘ + Qfifilcfl). (1i) “Indirect b€n€fit5”: The indiTeCt benefits to the 10W ability accrue from lower interest ability, the rates, whiCh remains the Same as in the Case of lighthouse (A), For the high- total benefits have to include the “indirect” benefits when stem from the capital market. The tOtal benefits of the lighthouse (B) to the high-ability is given by, aUHH __ g (1-5) _ 50H 5611 N—MH The total benefits critically depend on the indirect ‘ capital’ market eff t given by the CC 1 . t8 __ acfl Beg _ 91.21.5111 ggi ° rm, {tam + aMHHU [3)( N )l}- AS we saw’ BML IS negative, but on the other hand 2211. is positive [See Notes (11)] Therefore this i - 3 6M" ) ' , ndlrect . t eficct capital 1113.th being me - - - 'lld d the rel t' - gatlve or posrtive w1 epen upon a Ive weights We of these two terms" then have the following proposition [Proof in the appendix], Proposition 3 Indirect capital "“1"th benefits ”flig’lthOUSC (B) l , va (ted 6’ qua/[y by all types, though positive, are of a 16888?" magnitude than the ca 't 1 pz 0 , . market benefits of lighthouse (A), valued only by the mefl‘iciem. 1126 ~ . ° 1 ‘7 i 1 is th‘ I publlc input which has a greater impact on increasin It u 8 the homo. gene ‘ . - . . 1 ‘5’), in the economy leaves the ineffiment Wlth a lower incentive to mas quel- ade 1 ' n the 0886} . . sf lighthouse (A), the increase in homogeneity is higher compared to 1- lghthOQSG (B) Th . . . el‘gfore with the prowsron of lighthouse (B), the resulting slack in th e self- selection eon ‘ . - St. 1‘ aint IS 1955, and the capital market benefits are lower in magnitude as compared to 17 the lighthouse (A).5 One has to the“ compare this capital market externa/ity W171] the direct prOductivity benefits to find 011t whether the total benefits of the lighthouse (B) exceed that of lighthouse (A). (iii) The entry eflects; For the low ability, the entry effects rem ain the same as in the case of lighthouse (A). SEPARATING EQUILIBRIUM. Lighthouse(A) Lighthouse(B) ‘Direct’ effect (+) ‘Direct’ effect (+) ‘l 31, Interest rate effect (+) Interest rate effect (+) \ a“ Capita\(:/1+'¢1)rket effect 3:32;; 13:31"; (e 2e“ 4, The fiEUIe above summarises these conclusions (++ Indicate benefits of a gr t ea er mag- nitude as Compared to +). Under a 88133r ating equilibrium, the low ability e11 trepreneurs ) and (B). The productivity and are i I1 different thWeen the lighthouses (A . the IntCTCst rate I enefits they get in either case are the same. 5 F 5 is reason essentially sums up why a credit market. There is no relaxing of the self- public input which is more valuable to the haVe ' ' .o - s ill-overs m the _ wit} ML decreases. So any public input which increases the abiht 0 1 Such a good, M“ y f the efficient mere than t 1‘ t of the inefficient increases the degree 0f heterogeneity in the economy. AS mimicking is a made active the collateral costs in the credit market increase. 1‘ a Incite ‘tt l8 - 1y, on d epends assent/a1 between the types (A) and (B) then ' ' to chOOSe The decrsion ~ . . . ta] mar th ductivity . . 'rect pI'O . th derive pOSlthe d1 . with lighthouse (A), ey edlt I. . ' ' he the efficient types IS lug - in the cr ' uilibrlllIn (B) Suppose there exists a separating 6C1 'th lighthouse - benefits W1 ' 'nput ted public 1 - the targe has funds to build a lighthouse, ent d the governm market, an .v. at a on) [)3 e . . thou ( d t the [Nile DUbliC Input (llgh 59 i . A)) may (lighthouse ( . . ‘ on ould ' ' 5. ‘ ed in section t benefits, which 18 explor capital marke ' equilibrium “ itCh” to a pOOllng SW roge’ 1.4 The SS hem in lighthouses, the entrepreneurs are made 19 ‘ ting hat by Hives We have seen t ver Howe .n ter 8 of collateral are reduced. (1 the sorting costs 1 I I n (is ability, at “0118 as regar , - in .t can jeopardize the existence Of a Separating equihbrlumthe this increased homogenel y of a separating equilibrium depends essentially, on the economYlfiol’ since existence tiate themselves from the inefficient by Signalling. We effici ent types wanting to dlfleren the public inputs and the nature 0f the equilibrium. . en now turn to the relationshlp betWe ilibrium denoted above, equilibrium pabhofi's to the . equ WQ saw that in the Separatmg entrgh reneurs are. A iii—Ly ’1 ULL = N (N - NIH)” ‘ M”y , 1 —éH[(1 —fi)(—N~ ”W = —N— D Q _ _.___,—— a w . the ‘sortin , cost, hi fi)((N—M"))l s S, here S refers to g S 1 5H [(1 N en t .e the tern Q ' ad-wei lt loss if the of the of collateral forfeited as a de g1 ' e proportion 19 M . - . . . entrepreneur has a Ship-wreck- The term (”Nay ‘ 1) glves the utlllty oftfie hg/z-abzlzty in the case Of perfect information, SO in an asymmetric information case, 121:9 utility Is educed t0 the extent of these ‘ Sorting COStSa. r Our next step is to Show that there exists a pooling contract which dominates this separating equilibrium. We can then prove, along the lines of Hellwigl46], that the sequential Solution to this game iS a POOIing equilibrium. A pooling contract does not difie’entiate between entrepreneurs. We begin by conjecturing that this pooling contract in"GIVES all entrepreneurs paying an average interest rate given by F = 7A tug-'1) A7}? (We Will then prove in Proposition 4 that if this pooled contract Pareto dominates the se arat' uilibriurn then this contract iS indeed the SOlution to this sequential game). 9 mg eq , The DRYOfis to the entrepreneurs under this p001€d contract are given by, M ._ UL? : #(y — T) . MH _ Um, = "Rf-(y ‘ r) We See that the low ability entrepreneurs WOUId always prefer a pooled contract to the nce of the high-ability t separating ( ULL << Um), but the prefere ypes would deen d upon the 80 t' g costs 8 Sorting COStS or collateral COStS in this economy are inve 1' 1n - 3913’ related 7 ° ' l econom . We also see that t to «$9, , the degree of homogeneity In t 1e y he ave . It! rate 1‘ d r a pooled contraCt, ‘77, is Inversely related to ‘1‘- 11 e AIH‘ (The Pooled int ereSt rate is 8190 ‘ 1 t d t the proportion of low-ability borrowers which We A l riversely [‘8 a e O ’7’ Slime to b giver 1 large) Thus we see that given the parameters ,8 and 7, both S and p are inversely ‘73 S . ' relat Q i i I 1i hthOllse Wthh lIlCrease A, ltll the [OVlSlOIl Of a g S tl'llS hOln - A1 0 geneity Flt, a Separating equilibrium, the § - ts are reduced Wider *7? Q. 1.ng COS but the aVerage interest 20 rate under the pooling COntr ac t is also reduced. The efficient en trap renews W17] linear this sorting cost so long as they end up With a payoff which is more than the payofi" they will get under a pooling Contract This defines 3 Cut Off 5": given by: 1+ 5'(9) ‘ \ MH_ (1.4) V719) With 5 > S", a pooling contract will Pareto dominate the separating contracts. This is shown in the diagram below, where B1,, BH refer to the Zero Profit curve for the banks on contracts for low ability and high ability. The dashed line B p refers to the Zero Profit curve for the pooled contract. UL and UH refer to the indifference curves of the low ability and high ability. (21,0) and (771,011) mfer t0 the eqmlibrium separating contracts for the low-ability and the high-ability entrepreneurs 1‘ GSPGCtiver' The pooled zerO profit line tor the bank, B p, lies below the indifference curve for the high-ability borrower' The high-ability entrepreneurs“, in this case Will prefer a 1,001ng con tr act to the Separating 0119- (1",c’) refers to one Of the multiple pooling Contracts which StriCtly dominates the separating contracts (Th0) and (73> C . H) The p mOf below establishes that among all Of the multiple POOled contracts WhiCh dominate the separati 11g contracts (all Contracts like (7",6’) WhiCh lie below the indifference curve of the hi ability U . H and above the dashed line 319, the zero profit line Of the banks for pooled CC) 0 I - tracts): the n y I ooled contract which will be sustained as the equilibrium is the contr t (F c \ O O C , \ 0 [Prog 36 follows along the lines of Hellng [46] and IS given in the appendix]. ) :Proposition 4 Given that S > 5* , in the three stage game considere d b a 0216, the sequential equilibrium 0f the game is given by the optimal pooling contra t C ' 21 Figure 2; A Pooling Contract dominating the Separating Contracts (PH CH’) The proof thus relies on the refinement of the game being walled in the credit market lt'iple It is because of the sequential nature of this three stage game, that out of the 1““ P001ing contracts which dominate the separating contract given above, there will perSlSt , _ 6 only one pooling equilibrium given by (730)- While the inefficient entrepreneur always prefers the p001ing contract . “g compared to th e separating contract, the efficient entrepreneur s preference will depend on the co]. lateral costS- The intuition is that given a level of heterogeneity among e . reprenelll‘s 1!)ch §§ing signalling costs will dissuade the effluent entrepreneurs from di 4———-——- , . . . Brentia ' 6H§ 11“”qu mentions that this conclusion IS reversed if the Informed agents move first ting following the Cho - ' ‘ ' oweve , followin Wilson 69 w EK§_ i KrePS sequential equilibrium. H T g l l, 6 can assume th s t l s r 1 "I" a e stinguiSh among agents before these agents choose the contracts. This might also re fl t ec 180 cal un b cons - ' b law that all a ents be iven the san . . tr §ints, where 1'3 may required y g g ‘8 Opportunities. Therefore the \111 i formed party (the banks) moving first is a plausible assumption. n 22 themselves from the inefficient types. They are better off under a po oled/wza’zfierenaated contract. Increasing provision of public gOOds in the economy redaces the [eve] thet- erogeneity and thereby increases the Probability of a pooled contract dominating the separating Contracts. 1.5 “Switch Point” and the targeting of public in- puts From (4) we can calculate the critical point at which the pooling contract dominates, and the economy switches from a separating equilibrium to a pooling equilibrium- This “switch point” is given by [Calculation in the appenle], l—fiil; (1—7)(1 —fi) _— _— (1.5) 1 _ ME. ’7 N Where 7, 3 are the given parameters. . . 77 ' ' t ' ' In Our analysis, the “5WltCh pOlnt lS Importan , because It IS a point 01: comparison, local] th nefits of a lighthouse under a separating e(llll'libri'um 3*, between 6 be ”is a vis the Wolf 11g eqvilibrium. Public goods which increase the homogeneity beyond this switch pain 1: results in the capital market having pooled contracts which dominate t Contrfii ts A pooling equilibrium in this case, 18 soc1ally optimal because it . c creases the utilitf f both types. We can compare the marginal benefits of both light-h0u8 (A) and (B) a E this switch point defined above. This would tell us something about the ChOlCe Of the 1 i §htl10uses to be built. Q—‘:Q:.mparing tllC P3y0ff8 ‘0 the low-ability types under a [”01ng and a separating 23 Marginal costs and benefits of lighthouse (A) (MC = MB) \ Li fl Lighthouse (A) Separating Equilibrium v Pooling Equilibrium ‘switch’ point Figure 3; Targeted Public Input equilibrium, with the provision of lighthouses of type (A): We find that tlle follOWlIlg holds, [Proof in the appendix], Proposition 5 At the switch point, the marginal benefits of light/muss /Aj are higher under a separating equilibrium as compared to the pooling 89712725 flum- The marginal benefits of the lighthouse (A) are however, increasing under the separating equilibrium till they reach the switch point. After this the economy switches to a pooling equilibT’lum and the marginal benefits of the lighthouse (A) then start falling. We see in the figure above that the switch point separates the separating and POOIing equilibria. The marginal benefits (MB) are increasing when separating equilibrium ex 24 (MC = MB) Marginal costs and benefits of lighthouse (B) » ~ . .\ u o Pooling Equilibrium Lighthouse (B) Separating Equilibrium ‘switch’ point Figure 4: Pure Public Input ists, and falling, when pooling equilibrium exists. Given a. constant marginal cost(MC) of building the lighthouse q, the optimal amount of lighthouse (A) (where MB a MC) leads to a. pooling equilibrium. On the other hand, doing a similar analysis of lighthouS (B) e we get the following[Proof in the appendix], Proposition 6 At the switch point, the marginal benefits of the light/201155 (B) are higher under the separating equilibrium, as compared to the pooling equilibrium. The marginal benefits of the lighthouse (B) are however, decreas- ing both under the separating and pooling equilibria. However, the optimal amount of lighthouse { B ) leads to a separating equilibrium. In the figure above We see that in our model, to the left of the switch point we have 25 increased heterogeneity among agents, associated with a low level of public inputs in the economy. The separating equilibrium dominates here. In this scenario, a public good like lighthouse(A) which is valued mor e by the inefficient in the economy exhibits increasing marginal returns. The reason being that the extent of private signalling through collateral is high at this level and therefor0 greater benefits accrue to the efficient entrepreneur through reduction in these private signalling COStS- Lighthouse (B) on the other hand, benefits all entrepreneurs and reduces the heterogeneity in the economy to a lesser extent. The indirect capital market effects in the case of lighthouse (B) therefore increase at a decreasing rate. as then suggest that given the a constant marginal cost (1 of 1—%“ < building lighthouses - in an economy where the level of heterogeneity is high (1’ 15‘“ The above proposi tio Lilli—3'1), the optimal choice would be building lighthouses 0f type (A)- The optimal level of the lighthouses of type (A) take the economy beyond the SWitCh Point” Where the pooled contract dominates. On the other hand, building lighthouses Of type (B) would Inake the economy persist with separating contracts in the capital market. Thus, considering the indirect capital market benefits ' we would always end ”p we}, pooling EQUilibrium, if we build lighthouses of type (A). Therefore, when sorting COSts are high in tt1 (3 credit market indicating a greater level of heterogeneity among borrowers, build- ing I) uth inputs which benefit the inefficient results in the maximum capture of the eXteI‘rl ality of the public input which accrue through the capital market. To the right of the Switch point, under a pooling equilibrium however, we have to compare the benefitS “0111 the two types again to make a choice. This is done in the following section. 26 1.5.1 Public inputs and the pooling equilibrium Lighthouse A The total benefits 0f the lighthouse (A) are calculated as follows, (i) “Direct” benefits to the low ability, given as 4'16. There are no direct benefits to the high-ability, as before. a? will (ii) “Indirect” effects stemming frofr1 a reduction in the pooled interest rates 69, benefit both types. Essentially, with the P1“ OVlSiOIl Of a PUbliC 800d which increases the average ability of entrepreneurs in the economy, the risks associated with lending are lowered, and this gets reflected in the lower interest rates. Depending upon the (iii) “Entry” effects in this case, also will benefit both types. ates Opportunity costs of the alternative foregone: With the reduction in the intete‘5t r more entrepreneurs will enter the fraY- (B) Lighthouse B All these three effects are also reflected in the case of lighthouse WhiCh benefits both types. Additionally, the high-ability also benefits from the direct 3—? ’ . 69’ Whmh Summarizes productivity effects. We also see that the fall in the interest rate, the capital market effect is greater in magnitude to bOth types in this case, as Cowpared t0 the lighthouse (A). Thus in a regime where the pooling contract dominates, t here Will be 3,11 unambiguous choice in favor of the lighthouse (B) by both types. The Same is shown in the figure above, where there is a comparison of the benefits under the pooling qulilibrium. (++ refers *0 bCHCfits of greater magnitude as compared to +), Thus to the ri ght of the switch point, where the pooled contracts dominate in the capital markets _ L1 1% Optimal choice of the type of lighthouse to be built is 8., those which benefit all ent-1‘ epreneurs in the economy. 27 POOLFNG EQUILIBRIUM. Light hOUSC( A) Li ghthouse(B) A ‘Direct’ effect (+1 (+ ‘Direct’ effect (+) Interest 1' ate effec ) Interest rate effect 8L (++) Interest rate eff“:t ‘Direct’ effect (+) an (+) Interest rate effect (++) ‘type’ Of Public inputs that Should We have thus arrived at a, rough guideline fOI‘ the hip between n economy. The results suggest that there is a key relations be provided in a When the ublic inputs and the degree of heterogeneity in the economy- the type of p h. ve to 33 19 heterogeneity in the economy is high, the transactions costs iDCUrred in order g equilibrium are high. In such a scenario, a public input Which is hen- the separatin ability types results in higher benefits as compared to a PUblic eficial only to the low- good which benefits all types in the economY- 50, an economy should begin by buiI ding PUblic inpUtS which are targeted towards benefiting the less—efficient in the ecOIIomy ' - ' ' loitation of the externality which accrue to th ThIS will result in maximum exp e eCOnOmy via the capital market, With such public inputs, the economy will end up haying a p0019 (1 contracts which Pareto dominate the separating contracts in the credit market After building a critical level of such public inputs, only then should public goods which benefit all types should be built.7 In other words, if we explicitly take into consideration 7 ()ur result can also be seen to he in consonance with Boadway and Keen [20], Where using a different ‘28 the indirect benefits of PUbliC inputs via the Capital markets, those public inputs which are targeted to benefiting the inefficient in the economy provide the greatest benefits. Provision of public inputs which benefit all, or Which benefit only the efficient in the econ- omy should be taken up only after buildlng a critical mass of such targeted public inputs. 1.6 Optimality Rule for lighthouses This Section explores the optimality rules for the provision of the lighthouse using non- dlStOI‘ting, lump-sum taxatiOILS WC Shall be considering the costs and benefits of the lighthouse to the entrepreneurs under the two cases analyzed above (I) In the separating equilibrium, and till where we have a pooling equilibrium. (1) Effect of a lighthouse. on the Separating Equilibrium: The Optimal provision of light‘ houses oi type (A) will never result in the separating equilibrium, therefore the cost- benefit, analysis in this case will be restricted to lighthouses of type (B) , Where the marginal benefits are declining. The government maximizes the Welfare (W) amo h ngt e entrepreneurs, which is given as Alan: W = "LULL + "HUHH + nb7rb - T 9(8) \ffir ’nfOI‘I‘rlation structure than ours, they conclude that there should be a conventional “over-supply” of publi Q goods which are more valuable to the less efficient, and a conventional “under-supply” of DUbl‘ ‘ 1c gquS which are valuable to the efficient. a. Si nee labOr is non-elastically supplied in this model, it does not require any additional assumptiOHS 29 nL,nH and Nb refer to the nurnber of low ability, high ability entrepreneurs and the number of banks respectiveIY- 7th is the profits of the banks, which is zero in equilibrium. W is maximized s.t. the Government Budget constraint, where q refers to the cost of the lighthouseg. W = mesh-Aggy — 11+ "H(98)[%y ‘ 1 - CH0 - fiXLNMHH — qu (1.6) Maximizing W with respect to g we get the following, 6W 1 — [3) 66 N — M 5;; Q Era-(1%) + ””[CH—(T — 39in — 'B)(_N—£)] + ”’LCQBXULL) + nh(93)(UHH)° Enitjt) are the “direct” productivity effects referred to in the Samuelson Rule as EMRSy'9° I (t' ' 3) . iS The term in the square brackets refers to the indirect capital market effects. The n refer to the “entry” effects. (11) In the case oi the pooling equilibrium, ‘g’ refers to both types of lighthouses, (A) and (B), The government maximizes welfare (W) with respect to g, w = 2ni(g)[%(y-T)l+nm—T s.t. qg = T Maximizing W with respect to g and the government budget constraint we get g; = Eni(g)[% — %(%)l + Eni(g)Uii~ (1.7) fl are the direct productivity effects Which can referred to as ZMRSW. The indire0t CRID‘I t. al market effects are seen through a reduction in the pooled interest rateS, 01; being negative. The ”:5 refer as before, to the “entry” effects. Using the above notational 9T1“; lighthouse is assumed to he built at a cost q, which is given ex-ante. 30 conveniences, the effect Of a lighthouse "1 ”“5 economy can be summarized as, q :2: ZMRSy,g + ‘Capital market’ effect + ‘entry’ effect- 1.7 Conclusion This paper makes two contributionS— F irstb’, it analyzes the role of public inputs from an information theoretic approach- PUbliC sector economics is increasingly realizing the importance of imperfect information as a constraint on public policy. Private (asymmet- ric) information limits the set Of allocations that can be achieved in an economy While is has been mation asymmetry between the government and individua the nature of infor xist ammo a traces the effect of public inputs when asymmetries e analyzedl‘lfll, this paper individual transactors. Niarket allocations in this second best WOrld are often Contracts which are designed to prevent the inefficient from mimicking the efficient (SCI)- arating equilibrium), or by Contracts WhiCh go by the average attributes in the economy (POOIing equilibrium). When separating equilibrium exists, one of the tests of an ofiective PUblic policy is its ability to relax the self-selection constraints. We Show in ear mOdeI that a pUblic intermediate 800d, by reducing the heterogeneity among borrowers is able to rel ax this self-selection constraint in the credit market. Those public inputs which are better equipped to reduce this heterogeneity have higher indirect spill—overs. TherefOre, Wile 11 the level of public goods in the economy is low, our model predicts that public goods which are valued more by the inefficient. (lighthousc(A)), should be provided, An Optitnal provision of Such targeted public inputs results in the pooled contracts domi- 31 nating the separating contracts in the credit market. Here, the targeted public input dominates the pure public input. In other words, it makes sense to restrict access to public inputs when the marginal (303‘? Of another user is zero. When the credit markets are characterized by the pooling equilibrium, public inputs of both types, improve the average, (in this case the average quality of loans made), and encourage further lending in the economy. Public intermediate gOOdS can thus be perceived as “public signals which determine the level of socially Optimal investment. Secondly, in the light of the above, this paper calls for a. rte-assessment of the Cost- Benefit an a Iysis ofpublic inputs. Infrastructure and other public inputs can be justified without reference to the credit market — and yet, we have seen above that the indirect SDill-overs from the credit market are too large to be ignored. This result has key policy implications in determining the Optimal level of public intermediate goods in any economy. One has to go beyond ZMRSy,g given by the samflelson rule in the case Of public inputs. This is especially crucial since private investment decisions cannot be de—linked from the outcomes in the credit market. There is scope for further work in this area. The information asymmetry in t he Cred' 1t mar ket is ex-ante, giving rise to the problem of adverse selection. An extension to this mo (1631 Would be considering the effect of public inputs when the credit market is also Plag ued by moral hazard issues. Secondly, the taxes considered in this mOdel Were n0n_ diStQItionar-y. Further work can also be done on the nature of distortionary taxes and their effect on the marginal factor cost of building this lighthouse. This analysis also has implications for real world public policy, especially, government 901 icies in the credit Inarket. Much of the analysis on public interventions in the credit 32 market veers around the Optimal level Of SUbSidieS and loan guarantees to lenders/61, 38/ or redistributive policieslloi 49] ’ WhiCh improve Credit allocations. This Paper on the other hand, deals with public pI‘OViSiOn 0f baSiC inputs like infrastructure, health, literacy and other services and its effect 011 the credit market. The main feature of such public inputs is that an increase in their PFOViSion leads to a narrowing of the spread of abilities among agents. We show that it is preCisely this feature of public inputs which relaxes the Self-selection constraints and achieves Pareto optimal improvements in credit allocation. This feature of the public inputs also allows us to make conclusions about the targeting of PUblic goods to specific sections of the economy. There is thus a need to carry out more dis‘Segregated analysis of public sector capital. As we have shown, the effects of public inputs on the economy differ, depending on the type 0f the public input considered. M ()re importantly, it is seen that pilblie expenditures on infrastructure and provision OfserVices like education and health are normally justified on grounds of equity as being eXpellditures on ‘merit’ goods, or as interventions in the production of goods having Signifi cant positive cxtcrnalitics. This analysiS points out to another equally important lUStifi cation: public inputs, by equalizing ex-ante abilities among agents can relax the self‘ :3 Qlection constraints and improve the efficiency of market allocations. The ability of vari C) \1 5 public inputs to achieve this slack in the incentive constraints differs. In the light of t1”1 ‘1 result both the quantum of government expenditures, and the areas in which it s k 1 . 18 b Q i ng Spent, needs to be re-examined. 33 LA Appendix I.Proof of Proposition 2: The problem for the bank is, w WULL + (1‘7)UHH s.t. {n- .63} (i) the Zero profit constraint for the banks; [It—5m + (1 _ 1:9)561' = 1. (ii) the self selection constraint ULL 2 UL”. The usual strategy is conjecturing that the self selection constraint which is binding is ULL = UL”. We later verify that the optimal solution does satisfy the second self SEIectiOH constraint U H H > U H L. Substituting (i) into the utility function subject to (ii) 3 ~—— %L=Wl%‘(y~fi—fiCL(1—MNI))‘CL(1‘%L)-ZL]+(1-7)[Mn( N (ch? CL} N M” flc”(l — 7%)) — CHU ‘ l‘72“) - an +Al7v"(y“ “AT; — 30111 - 1%)) -014“ _ 1173‘) _ Zr] _ M [#(y __ 31;: _ecH(1_MUZ))—cH(1-%h)-Zrl. WherQ A is the lagrangian multiplier associated with (ii). Setting 3L CH 6 = 0 gives us, (1 — 7)[(1— KNEW? - 1)] = “(l-flexed) >0' Whi Q}‘l implies that (ii) is binding. Using the above result, it is easy to show that 51’ < 0 CL ’ . _ , - - ' 3 _ lV - WillQll ifllphes tklat CL : 0 Putting thlS Into (1), we gCt TL — m. Pllttlng these results in (i i ) We get, 1 “(919711) 1_ML N CH = We & lestitllte for r” from (i), and solve for the same above to get the Optimal value 6-H. 34 We get, A! ., _IL‘NQ 172‘) (3” ., It can easily be verified that U” H > UHL’ and that our conjecture was right. II.Proof of Proposition 3: The benefits to the high ability through lighthouse (A) is given by, 3UHH a9(A) N- NM” 1’ {(81:11, )[(1— —fl)(——— ———)] (1.8) USjng the definition of CH given in Proposition 2, we can write, 36H NMH(1‘fl)(MH ~N) aML = [MH(N — ML) — HAM (1.9) We See that (1.9) is negative since (Mr! —‘ N) is negative. Therefore, (8) is positive. The benefi ts to the high ability through lighthouse (B) is given by, BUHH y (1 — )8) _ 36” + 8C” _ N - 55“) N N H 8M1, 6M” )( Mflll- (1.10) 6C . Frorrl (1.9) we know thatd iti— is negative. 48;, is then given by, 00H NMLU — .3)(N — 1‘4le W}; = MN — ML) — HMLUV — Mm]? (1‘11) (1.1 l D is positive. Therefore, the condition for Proposition (3) to hold is that, BC 06” I .” l > |—-—l BAIL 81W” 2:» MH(N -' JWH) > MLUV ‘ ML) ME, — Mg 1V1” — ML =>1V > A!” + NIL Which is true as per our 35301111) tion. III.Proof of PI‘OPOSit'iOn 4: Suppose bank j deviates from the pooling Contract (7,0) and offers another contract (F75) _ it will be accepted by all the high ability and not the low ability. Since the high ability types are more likely to accept a contract involving collateral to signal their ability. Consequently bank l 1' eceives applications from all the above average, high ability entrepreneurs. Banks that have Offered (F, 0), will then be left with below average Sample of the population. Since ('7‘, 0) only breaks even at the population average, all applications to (710) will be rejected in Stage III. Knowing these rejection strategies, all entrepreneurs, both efficient and inefficient, will apply 0111)’ for (fl 5). This is contrary to Our Earlier assumption that only the high-ability Will Emmy for this contract. Thus, under equl'libr-mm strategies, deviations to the optimal pooling contract will be rejected and it 0811110 1: be upset by any separating Contract (7, 5)- Therefore, (F: 0) Will be the equilibrium 13001ng contract, and the sequential solution to this 3 stage game considered. IV-Q Qlculation of the ‘Switch P0int" A8 p Q :r (1 .5), the definition of the switch point, we have N+cH(1—fi)(N-MH) = MH": (1.12) USi ‘ ' - —- ____———N—————'- we have 11 g the definition, r : IWH“7(1”H”AIL), N7(MH — ML) MH — "((MH — ML) CH(1 - fixN " NIH) MAM—ML) we have Us‘ - - - . — 111 g the definition, (.11 : m—BMMN—MH)’ (1 — [3)(N - MH) “/ [VIM/V _WBMAN - 1W”) — MH — “/‘(MH - ATL) 36 Which gives us, (1 —mNMH — (1 — BMNMH 4" (1‘ WNML ~<1— 5W}. +(1~fl)7A//2 [I And this implies, ll mm) Mm -' W1 ~ 7)) — NMH<(1— mu — 7) => ML _ MH[MH(1‘5)(1 —7) -+:7.:\fv(v—-(1—B)(1—~)))J :> A41, = MH[1— MW -7) N 7 J 1_LWJ._ 1—L‘1d — “r N -Pl~oof of Proposition 5: At the switch point, the paYOffS '30 the high-ability entreprenems With a separating Contb #3013 just equal the payoffs they would get With an undiffer entiated/ pooled contract This payOfi is defined as per equation (1'12)' sepQrating Equilibrium:- For the type aL entrepreneur, it is easy to see the m . l argina beYLQ fit of the light house (A), BULL _ aULL _ 3/ 89M) _ (9le _ N (1-13) F . 1‘0 11‘ (1.8) and (1.9), we can calculate the marglnal benefit of lighthouse (A) to the type a” Q neur _ lltrepi‘e 7 BUHH _ BUM” A/IH(1_/3)2(N "11”!!!)2 fl‘ 05m) ’ BML [MH(N—ML)—[3ML(N_ W (1.14) 37 The marginal benefits of the lig’;hthouse (A) tO this economy as a whole under a sep ting 313 equilibrium regime are thus given by (1'13) + (1-14)- We see that the marginal benefits W > O. are increasing in gm), Slnce BA! 1. Pooling equilibrium:- At this point, the Inarginal benefit of the lighthouse (A) to the low—ability entrepreneur is given by, BULWZQQEZ:£_ (1—7lMH 115 89(A) aML N M71! — 7(MH - MLll2 ( ' ) The marginal benefit of the lighthouse (A) at this point to the high-ability entrepreneur is given by, 8U 8 UH ”Y My H7 7 __ x (1.16) a9(A) .— aML ’ [My — «My — Map (1-15) + (1.16) gives the total benefit of the lighthouse (A) t0 the economy under a 90011 11g equilibrium regime. It is however decreasing in 9H) Since both $1321 and 952%}?- are '< o. (”HIS the marginal benefits of the lighthouse (A) are increasing under a separating equi- libri Kim , and they are decreasing under a pooling equilibrium. We now have to show that at the switch point, defined by (1.12), the marginal benefits of the lighthouse (A) under “1% rating equilibrium exceed the marginal benefits under the pooling GQUilibrium. $6193 At L118 switch point, given by (1.12), “assume true” that (1.13) + (1.14) > (1_15)+ (1.16), Z, MH<1—.6>2(N —- M”)? 2 > ., mm ‘L lAIHUV —~ AIL) — [3A,],(N - NIH” [1)!” — 7(MH _ AIL“? (l—fi)(N-MH) (27—1) _________/ > . fix— :> [MH(N — A41.)— fiMLUV — MHll W" ‘ “M” “ ML” N(A’IH—A’IL) . 1_—. : 1V 1 t; “ - ,an(I__——\___._weiaveo Usl I 1 g the defimtlomi CH : MMN—Aim-aileN—Mn) Mil-*erML)’ 38 Show, CH(1 --fi)(N— NIH) rm W > T We now use the definition 0f the SWitCh point given by (1.12), and we have, MHFxN > F,/27—1(MH—ML) =>F(MH‘ WOW” ‘Md > N Again using the definition of ? given above, we have to show, N(MH - «27 —1(MH —’ MLfl > N My —7(MH - ML) Since ’1 < 1 and 7 > m > 0 for all 7 7g 1, we therefore have, (Ii/[H — V27 —1(MH _ AM My —’)’(MH ‘ ML) The Inarginal benefit of the lighthouse (A) at the SWitCh point is greater under the sepaatating equilibrium compared to the pooling equilibrium. VI - broof of Proposition 6: SGDQ Ta ting Equilibrium: The marginal benefits of lighthouse (B) to the inefficient is given by \- 3 aULL 3/ — — 1.17 (99(3) N ( ) Frq) 1*) the proof of Proposition 3, we get the marginal benefits of the lighthouse (B) to 1 thq} (efficient entreprei’ieurs, '» — ' v N ~ A! ()UIIH y (1 (3) _ LC” + dc” 1—fi) —\fl . (1.18) 69(3) — N + N C” (BML 8114”)“ ( N )1 39 (1.17) + (1.18) give the marginal benefits 0f the lighthouse (B) ‘30 this even ' omy as a whole under a separating equilibrlum regime. Pooling Equilibrium: The marglna1 benefits of lighthouse (B) to the inefficient under the POOIing equilibrium is given by, 6UL'7 : Ej—\ A—A/MA’IH-ML) 1 89(8) N [Ii/[H - 7([1/111 — NILHQ ( 19) The marginal benefits of lighthouse (B) to the efficient under the pooling equilibrium is given by, aUH'y _ EL+ (7)(MH-‘ML) ‘ N [NIH—7(MH—W (1.20) 59(3) (1.19) + (120) gives the total benefit of the lighthouse (B) to the economy under a p001ing equilibrium regime. We {3 Ist show that at, the switch point, defined by (1.12), the marginal benefits of the Ugh t house (B) under the Separating equilibrium exceed the marginal benefits under the p 001 i ng equilibrium. At t he switch point (1.12), “assume true” that (1.17) + (1.18) > (1.19) + (1_20)_ (1 — We”) __ {99; + 29.44“ ‘WN ’ MM} > W N 8ML aMH N [Mu — 7(MH _ Mn]? Usih g (1.9) and (1.11), we can rewrite (1.17) + (1.18), and we therefore have to show 1*, . 1—. 2N—MH)[MH(N-MH)-ML(1V-MLfl “#1) ‘1' {( fl) [(111]!(N—A’IL)‘B/UL(N’1”H)l2 } > (Mu—MLXQ‘r-ll [NIH—WM'IH—IVLHQ UR ‘ - - .— M m . “ 1 1%)?)- the dfi‘fimtlon, CI! = M”(N__ML)-BML(N—MH)‘ “'9 have to show, l—f3)((f (1—[3)2(CH)2(N—A1H)|AIH(N-AI”)—A’IL(N—AJI_L)1 L N "—1) + i [N(MH—ML)]2 } > (Mn-4400741 [Ilfu—~1(1\1H-ML)12 40 , ' . —_ , ) 1V“IUH—AIL n-mc ) 0—9)) CHW" M”, > \M :> g H { (N(MH"1‘!L )1 } [1"IH-W(MH-ML)1 NUUH—ML) N . . - '1 —— A c Usmg the definition of 7 =‘— NH , ’7UUH‘AIL) ’ We have to Show, ,,_ 2 <1 — .B>CH[N(MH —- MM + (1 '5) “WW - MHHN — My — ML} (27 —1)r2 [NUVJH -— Md]? } > T At the switch point(1.12), we have (1 ‘ ’8)CH = W, we therefore have to Show, (MH? - N M _ N _MH)[N(MH__A,[L)]+ N I AI], [N—A/IH _AlL] > T2(2’7—1)(A4H—1l/IL)2 In the proof to proposition 5, we have Shown that, Mm: — N > r\/2v - 1 ( My — ML) Therefore, in order to prove propositiOn 6, it SUffices to show that, M % _ WWW” ~ ML)] + (My? — NW ~ MH - MI} > (Mm — N)? \MH :> N(MH __ N1134— (1wH7— N)(N— (WM) — (MHF‘NNWL > (fl/IHF~N)(N— A’IH) => N(MH — M.) > (Mu? - NW1. :NMH > NIHML? ML 7A’1L +(1— 7')MH :>NA’IH > NMH \ ~ . V5 1 ch IS true because, AIL 71"IL +(1— ’7)A[H < 1 It i & thus proved that at the switch point, the Marginal benefits of the lighthouse (B) are: mating equilibrium as compared to the pooling- equilibrium I greater under the sep 41 We now show that the Marginal benefits 0f the 1ighthOUse (B) are de creasing bot/2 under the separating equilibrium and Under the pooling equilibrium Separating Equilibm‘m" Refer “'17) + 0-18) as MBS the Marginal B fit {1' ht v ene s 0 1g — house (B) under the separating equilibrium. itIBS=2_iZ+(—L—%)m+{( )[(AZBMH)1MH(N*MH)-ML(N—ML)l N ”(N B ML) ‘ BMLUV — MH)l2 } (1.21) We have to show that 95%;? = 23%? + %’5 < 0. T0 Simplify the calculations, denote the t<9I‘In 1'11 the denominator, [MH(N — ML) " flMLUV-MW/ as 45 and the tel“1min the numerator (1 “ 3)2(N ~ MH)[MH(N ’ M”) .. ML(N — ML“ as Q. Thus, MBS can be \Nritten as, _ 3g (1—5)(CH) 9 M85 — N+_1\T\+ 53 Which implies that , 8MBS _ (1 — [3) ac” + {W1 — WW — Mn)(2ML ~ N aML “ N all/IL @4)+92¢(6(N\ M ”+11; 11)] m — N BMH + W ) L / {MN —' MHXN — QMHH — QQ‘MN - M }+ (1)4 w (1.23) 42 Adding (1.22) and (1.23), and collecting terms, we simplify the Semein th [/1 "mg (5’ 0 0W1 way:- The coefficient of the term (1’2 ( 1 “ (3)2 is, {(N — MHMN 1M”) — (N .. 2M5); ~ LMiW — MH) — MLtN — M )J} 4 V . — , 5110“,: + Which we see 18 less than LCI'O. To that, We see that the (+) term has been proved . . - d the - . to be POSitiVe 1n Pmposmon 3’ an ( ) term 13 negative because 2M3 > 2M L- Take the coefficient of the term 324) whiCh is, {13(N — MH) + My — (N - ML) " 5%} - v This term is less than zero because: {(1 _ flMMH + M L — N ]} is less than zero. - , ‘ (1‘5) Bea C r The third term to be conSIdeled 15’ { N {IBM}, —+— %fi:]}. This term is less than be“) ac . t because it follows from“) [fi%1< O and [51%] > O, and we showed in proposithn 3 tha , | 86” l > I BC” 1 aML 8M” ‘ 4 . 't '8 shown that 6MB . And the denomma‘OT» ‘1’ > 0 Thus 1 l 35532 15 less than zero. Pooling equilibrium: Denote (1.19) + (1.20) as MBP, the m - argmai benefits of the light- house (B) under the pooling equilibrium. It is given as, __ 2y (Mu - ML)(2’7 ~ 1) MBP — N + [MH‘7(MH_TL)]2 (1 24 61x18 ) aAlB - M . . ) We see that 5111‘ < 0 and '45!” < 0. Therefore, d913, LB Notes to Calculations:- (I) The Perfect Information Equilibrium. The problem is, aqu—Mi(y—T)‘—(1_ Mi)Ci\Z M M ‘{r. a}, u —’ N N i- S.t. N 7"- + (1 — thflq z: 1 (1.25) Plugging the Zero Profit constraint Of the bank into the Utility function and differenti ating it w.r.t. c,- gives us, 3U“ : 6c,- M, (1‘ y) (B — 1). Which is negative, since fl is less than one. TherefOI‘E, 8-8 per the Kuh Tu k r conditions, II- C 3 c1 = 0. Putting this illto the Zero PTOfit condition Of the banks w t h 'nterest rates, v ege t e 1 Ti 2 £7, as the recipro cal of the entrepreneur’s ability. (11) Effect oi \‘ighthouses on collateral: From Proposition 2 't a we can re—WII 6 CH as, C ::= N(MH — ML) H MH(N — ML) “ 3M __a_C_H_ _____ NMH(1-l6)(MH —N) 3ML [MH(N — ML) - BMW We See that it is negative since (1W H — N) is negative. 9511. = ”ML“ ‘5)(N-ML) 8M}; [lWH(N - NIL) - [3&le W11 i ch is positive. 44 Chapter 2 Pubh’c versus Private Signals in the Credit M arket 2 .1 Introduction The level of investment in any economy, a large extent on the business environment in that economy. A Coun tr . . ° ' WbICh has a poor implementation of laws and regulations governing Its bUSiness 00111: l‘ . . ts, a 12' level of bureaucratic inefficiency and COIIUPUOU, Poor quality of DUblic set 1gb Vi infrastrucwrea political instability etc. ..will not attract a high level Ofpriva . e flourishing of private initiatiVes Y1 environment conduCive to th Deeds t obe f0 11 the b Stered - - ' we » - . . bot 1,1 by the institutions Wlthm an economy as pu 1‘0 pOllCleS Wh lCh shape it Tug 0 taken together, may be said to constitute what is today Called ‘ t“' the u 1 cent years there has been an increasmg availability of empirical ~ re ‘ i ll 45 M subject} Based on such data, several cross-country studies find that 5/1089 was C011!) . . j - . which rank low on this 500131 nfrastructure index (countries Plagued by corruption, . ' I) ~ . . . predatory busmess practlcesa a d rent seekmg actiVities) are also Stuck with 10W [eveIS of investment, lower product1v1ty and l()Wer levels of income and growth. Mauro[56], ' tin o . . , . for example, uses a data set CODSIS g f SubJECtlve indices of bureaucratic honesty and . . ct of . _ . efficiency to find a negamve imp a. Corruptlon on investment levels. According to ' a 0n . . . . . - him, if BangladeSh were to achieve e Standard deVIatlon increase in its bureaucratic efiiciency (which would take to the level 0f bur eaucratic efficiency in Uruguay), its in— vestment rate would rise by five percentage POintS and its Yearly GDP growth would rise by half a percentage point. Hall and Jones[45], conclude that Countries which achieve high rates of investment in phySical and human CatlDital and thereby high rates of prOduc' t'wity, consistently score high on the social infrastructure index. Recent Studies in the - - ‘ 0 indicate that wide spread r . ”ammo“ economies\25l, als p edatlon and insecure Property rights have depressed capital accumulation in these countries in all it . _ . . . S duneneions. And lastly 811,111ng WeilGSl, arrives at a Similar conclusmn With TeSpect t , o . . I‘ej . investments in the developing economies. gn dlrect Based on the above empirical results, the object of this paper is to pr 0 Did e u - . ‘ 1 ' f astructure indicators and inv a DOSS'b m1 Cro” link between soc1a in r estment (1801'st 1 1e 8. 18h by 6 go i 11130 the theoretical reasons explaining corruption or bribery undertake n "“8 (See Bartlhanlfll for an excellent revieW), but given that varying levels of social infrast ru 1 $118 laLBSt being an extensive Survey by the World Bank Group [70] courl‘ '09 between late 1999 and mid-2000, on the business environment fan _7 r1 ,. ing firms) C; Bug i it ‘84:; Environment Survey, (W BES)» 2000- 46 . . . unfit)" to countr ‘ - exrst (which differ from 00 Y, or even differ across reglon . . S Withlh the same country), I would like to explain their relation to the borrowing and investment decisions of firms. ' id) is iv - . A common explanation Wh g en 18 that investing in such regions is generally . ‘ ' ' . . 1') Wh . . risky. This generalization IS t1” ”‘3’ en we conSIder that lenders (banks) can deVise _ risk - contracts which can separate the y prOJeCtS from the not so risky. Therefore, the . is Question I will be trying to answer that Why Would a lender (presumably, a bank in . _ i ' - - . this case) look to these economy W de mdicators 1nstead of firm-specific indicators 1n taking its lending decisions? The mainstay of the explanation Will be the existence of asymmetric information in the credit market- I essentially bUild 0“ tWO models, (a) Hellwig[461a which takes into consideration ex— ante, pre-contractual adverse selection PTOblems in a. three stage dynamic game being played between the lenders and borrowerS in the credit market l and (b) Aghion and Bommlll, which deals with post-contractu a1 mo 1 h ra azardissue ' h dmak E' mod h hwnho ' Sn t e cre it r et. arlier els ave s o W Imperfect infor t‘ 1 111a 1 on. . . . I); . market may give rise to credit rationing [65]. However, incrEflSing the the credit C011 the banks to include both the interest and the collateral all 0We d for th t Space of e th ' l self-selection device and a ‘ - possibil' e banks usmg collatera as a VOIdmg the prob] Ity of e sel . 16] In this aper I allow banks to simultaneous] of advers es;- COI ‘ b t ' ' ddition to the Dre-contr - rates and lateral requirements, I! In a aCtual mfomlation . In MOI the lines of Stiglitz and Weiss [?], I add another level of inf Gt l g 01‘ Ination aSYIn In t. 1, 16 form of a post-contractual, moral hazard problem. r This paper then shows that due to this interaction between SGleCtio d . we 47 effects, private signalling loses its rdevance as a Self-selection device. Lenders would then increasingly resort ‘0 imbue Signals like social infrastructure indicators. It is through this link that such public indicators Which define the business environment of a firm affect their investment decisions. I then go on to show that credit rationing could be more severe in economies having a poor SOCial'infraStructure. Thus, in a simple theoretical model WhiCh explicitly takes into accoth a parameter of social infrastructure (the possibility that because 0f I300r implementation of laws, Corruption, need for ‘irregular payments’ to bureaucrats etc... firms do not earn their full revenue, which they would under ideal circumstances), I Show how economies ranking low on the corruption index have higher levels of investment. rThis WOU1C1 also explain, for example, given the global nature 0f investment portfolios, there iS an increasing emphasis on ColleCting and understanding country risk measurES by institutional investors. The paper is organized as follows, section 2 introduces the model Section 3 estab- lishes the key result of the existence of a pooling equilibriUm in the Cred '1; 1 mark . ' - 6t. Sec 4 discusses the effect of social Infrastructure on this equflibrium and h tion : t e given in section 5. 2- 2 Model A9672 t5 ._ Identical agents who are endowed with 1 unit of labor (l) Wh‘ . , ’ lch they ”18:1 .\ .tically. They are also endowed With wealth (w < 1), i . Clin bar 1 k or used as collateral to obtaln loans from the bank- The agents a ’ are risk.“e . lit 11v“ ral, for 2 periods and they produce 111 the first pcrlod and consunm in th (Esccorul 7F} ' lose 48 If agents have 2 choiceSI to be workers in a routine activity WhiCh 0111}, reqm'res ] b (and a 01' thus dePOSit w in the bankS) a or to undertake an entrepreneurial Project which requires . - bo ' - . them to combine 1 null; 0f 1a 1‘ Wlth 1 unit of capital. Workers get a deterministic return Z. Potential entrepreneurs have to borrow 1 unit of capital in order to undertake the project. More about the entrepreneurial preject will be said below. Banks Banks in this econonly are riSk‘neUtl‘al and act as Betrand Competitors in a market where they obtain elaSt’icaHy SUPpIied fLlnds. We normalize the gross deposit rate at which the banks Obtain theSe funds to be one. Since we assume banks to be Betrand competitors, they make zero profits in equilibrium on the projects they lend- Projects : The rel: urns from the project are Uncertain. The uncertainty in this Proled’ stems from two sources, Ecr- Ante _ The pig-xgct has a success probability of p. This is however not known ex. ante either to the potential entrepreneur or to the banker' What the entrepreneur does know ex-ante is the return from the project, if it is successfu1_ It is i d n eter . . ° . 111111111 returns from a successful pI‘OJeCt that this model takes into the SociaI . g the Infr the economy. In an ideal situation, a successful project win .Yiel d the ent tructure of T e e u " . e . Yield (YF)- However, firms lose revenue in a business environment whj h at Its fu 11 c . 1 . - , OHS - . and predatOTY- 1 base this observation on the World Bank Business Environ trzctwe e nt Sufi/9y 2000 (“.IBES). Respondents in this survey were asked if it Was Common f ' Or firm . . . ‘ . . 8 Lin . hue. f business to have to pay some Irregular additional payments’ to the" 0 get things (ion 7 e . 77 In %outh Asia and Developing East ASia more than 60% 0f the firms ‘d 831 this Was alx ‘\ V‘Ri. that quell payments were at least frequently required. In the transition 9 ‘ ' ,conomie,g L Of yb‘ mostly or frequently the case. In Africa, more than half of th e fi ’ rms reDort ed 49 Central and Eastern Europe, around a third of the firms provided such responses. Only in the OECD countries and the industrialized East Asia could this response be described WBES as rare - around 12% of the firms. To gauge the actual impact of such payments: . n blic enquired about the total percentage of revenues paid as “Unofficial payments to pu of Eastern and officials. These payments are the highest in the transition economies dia, Pakistan Central Europe at 5.5% of revenuesa in South Asia (which consists of 111 of the total and Bangladesh) it was 5%, While in developing East Asia, it was 45% and 83% revenues, In contr 3315, 86.3% of the firms in the newly industrialized East ASia’ b ibeS lE’l of the firms in the OECD countries reported paying 0% of their revenue3 in I Therefore in this model, ICt the Proportion of firms who have to Sufie on account of such payments be ’7- Let this lower yield be denoted Y1, efilisi bUl» potentially sufiet a range of lOW yields on this project on account of such p33 3L whethel 1 summarize .1" to be Y1” and YL < YF). Since such Payments are unoffici their yield is YF 0‘ YL is the Private information of the firms - ' 7 ‘3 thus an indicator of social inirastructure, which is public information. Higher the 7 hi gher . , is t h e pro ' of firms who have to lose revenue on account of factors such as Corrupt' portion ion a l) - Fiberx 10b- by ing for award of government contracts, payments for prOCUrement f o . - - ; , IiC Serv. etc - .. and greater IS the Size of thls shadow or unofficial economy? 1063 2This assumption implies that firms who choose to make such payments are 1 t ‘10 cnga . ged in . tion ’(where predation includes rent-seeking and dupe activities [25D Therefore it is preda» . , ve d. t1] \ i h . -. . - ry lfierent from L. Murphy, be leifcr and Vlblmy hypothcmb [bl where firms choose between product‘ (1 ‘ We an Preda - . tory 3C1: lV’itiee depending upon the returns guaranteed to them by the system. Here we haw ' 1 e a. Sing 8 produC- lcct, but on account of the poor social infi'astmcturc, some firms have to m ' 'dkc illegal paymL )nts tiv ‘ I“ pro to i i I i ‘ Qarr out the pro Ject. This assumption lb Closer to the CFOSSI'na ' ? ' y n and Kim [J hypotheSis where some 50 Ex’POSt -' In the pOSt-contractual ex-post scenario, the success probability (I?) get-9 de— . they termined. p is an indicator of the effort put in by both types of entrepreneurs: once 1y - - ° hosen on secure a loan contract and have to implement the pI‘OJeCt. It IS optimally C ‘ ' tion . . an lIldlca after acceptance Of the 10311 contract. SlnCe the probability of success p IS 1] , . . .nd Boltoni of the the individual’s effort, there IS an effort Cost (3(1)) Following Aghion a we assume a uniform convex cost funCtlon across individuals, 2 A 4 6/19): 22—. The Project is high yielding. We exPhCitly assume ‘high yielding’ to be» mm the pm] A 5 Y,- — 1 > Z, Vz' e {F, L} - The expected value 0f the net retumfif exceed the opportunity cost 0f the PTOject to all agents. Thus there exist incentives for all agents to undertake the pro j eet. 2.3 Capitafi Market Equilibrium Taking, into consideration, this two-layered information asymmetry, the Q . . apital market e(allilibrium is obtained In the followrng way, Th e optimal loan contract: Assume there exists only 'a standard debt; . contract for investing funds (issuing equity is costly). As in the model of Bester [16], banks ofl‘ 81' a loan contra ct consisting of a pair (7', c) where r IS the gross interest rate Charged l aJId c V . . firlh§ are moral and WOllld nOi; engage ‘n COI‘TUDL practices, and some firms are amoral and would eh . 7 ' . gage in Qofluption. In this model however, the morality of firms is not fixed or given, but, it is a function of the 1)aram0t9r '7, which is determined by the iUStitlltiOIlS and Public policies of an economy, and thereby an 1 e I ‘ able to change. is the collateral that the borrowers are willing to put up. We also make the following additional assumption, . . . . b 12k a A 6 Collateralzzmg 23 costly- Collateral of value C; to the borrower gwes to the a value of [3a, in the event the borrower defaults, where [j E (0,1).3 . t - As in Hellwig [46], the a 3 stage sequential game is being played in the Credit marke 1 This game explicitly takes into account dynamic reactions of borrowers- The Opmna loan contract can be Seen as a Solution to a 3 stage game, Stage 1: Banks offer contracts (7" ’ C‘l' ex Stage I]: Given the con tr acts the borrower i chooses p such that it maximize es he er we: to Pected revenue from the projed' net Of (a) repayment COSt (b) eflort costS- T ebOt chooses the contract most attractive to him. He can choose only a single CO “ac" . waved in Stage III : The banks may accept or reject the loan applications they have ‘ Stage ll. The Optimal contract (73,51); Vi = H, L is a set of contract Offers wh‘ , 1C1: determine the equilibrium in this 3 stage game. i.e. given (1%, (3,.) Vi = H, L - Banks make zero profits on each contract and _ N 0 bank has the incentive to offer a different loan contract than the one Offered. Since this game is sequential, the equilibrium considered will be the Sn}; ga e perfe t 01‘ Sequential equilibrium. The usua1 condition that each agent’s strategy be th e hes st response to the other agent 8 strategies is applied not only to the OVerall game but BT11 6 assumption of the bank not being able to realize the fun value for the Collateral in C85 e of (lefa‘Iu by the borrower, apart from having real world justifications is also crucial for the existence 1 . . ' ' 0 mini 1 ibrium in a risk neutral environment. See Clemenz [26]. 52 to every decision node in the game tree, regardless of whether this node is reached in equilibrium. We define Uij to be the utility to agent of type i applying for a loan contra”t meant for type j. 2.3.1 Equilibrium When the banks can distinguish types The s. As a benchmark, we solve first the (335%? when banks can distinguiSh between type . e aware banks are aware of the illegal payments that law: to be made by firms, Le they at f . . bsence O of Whether the revenue of the firms 15 YF 0T YL. This is the solution 111 the a rd al haze» adverse selection, when banks have t0 tackle only the post, contractual mot _ they after problem. They are not aware of the effort that will be put in by the borrowers get the contract. The problem for the entrepreneur is, 2 Man: U“; = PiKYi — Til " (1 - p-i)Ci — E; 3.1:. Pisriaci ill the Zero profit constraint for the banks: Rb E pm- + (1 “ POfiCi = 1. my the seli selection constraints U,,- 2 U , j. (iii) The Individual Rationality constraint U5,- > Z. In the full-information case, the self-selection constraints do not bind. he I‘efOI. bOrrower solves 6, the - . .2 ‘A’ICLIE’ ’ pi(yi _ ri) _ (1 — pi)ci _ p? P2571461 S-t- Rb E Piri + (1 — PDBC, = 1 U?’. 2 Z 11 wllere 1); refers to the equilibrium Choice of effort by the entrepreneur and U?- ” TQfErS t0 the equilibrium level of utility, once the effort has been chosen. Before we give the f n , u 53 information solution we see that the equilibrium effort level pg, given the interest rate 7'" and collateral c,- has to satisfy the following conditions, 2.1) P:=yi —7‘i+ci where 0 0, but g—f? lS ambiguous. 511106, 6 6R1) 3 . _ p1 613' 2 5) — i + z‘ — i — ' ( ' 8r,- 1) (7" 56 l 67} where (973‘ < O The effort that the entrepreneurs put in, which defines the success probability (P) 15 k5 would negatively related to r, but positively related to the collateral, c. Thus the ban require the borrowers to use all their wealth as COllater a1, and determine the interest rate SUb‘jeCt to this‘ Loan applications With any other amount of collateral would be related by the bank in Stage III and knoWing this’ in eQUilibrium no such application would be forthcoming The 3011113011 ‘30 Ti in (4) is then a solution to a quadratic equation. “ 15 bank, given obtained by plugging p: and Ci ; 'w in the the Zero profit condition of the in (i) 4. .. e deflmd in) When the banks can SBPaIate Out the types , individual COntractS can by the banks, such that corruption Can be weeded out to an extent As we See bd firms who engage in corrupt practices are charged a higher interest rate mpared t0 , as Co the, more honest firms. 67} 0 8K < => TF < TL (2.6) 4We take the root with the lesser value. Both the lenders and the borr kn OWEI‘S 0“? garne, and if there exists more than one solution, the lowest among these (viz th 8 rules of the o o S ~ the high” effort. p ) Will be compatible With pareto efficiency. OCzated With 2.3.2 Asymmetric information equilibrium in the Presence 0f both adverse selection and moral hazard: ' l The full information equilibrium does give us a clue into the equilibrium that we W111 , n reach when the banks are unaware of the reanueS of the firms who apply for loans considering the separating equilibrium as a SOlution, we see the follOWinga as w , In the r—c Plane, totally differentiate U; = ((1%L2 ~ Ci) to get in the context of bOIIO £12 a 22* — 1 (2.7) dq T T < 0 d Wwaf (7) eStabHSheS that the indifference cur ves 0f the borrowers in the r-c Space are do t make 0 sloping, and satisfy the single crossing property. viz. the borrower who expects d m the axe unofficial paYments and get a lower return YL: has a lower MRS 35 Comp . ~ - duC‘ilo borrower who eXDeCtS his full Yleld from the pro J ect Yp. For a small re - 1m 1 tome“ interest rates, the \atter is w mg to post more collatera as Compared to the condition f th ist - . - . . However, the other or e ex ence of a separating ethbnum IS that the zero—profit Curves for the banks should be flatter than the indifferenc ”-"Ves of the borrowers. We show that this condition cannot be satisfied and therefo , e’ the tYpes Cannot be sorted out by the banks. The contracts cannot be self selected . and we have tlle following, [Proof in the appendix]. T1 N art-existence of a separating eqUil'ibTium in the credit market W’ll en collateral is also used to monltor the effort put 111 by heterogenous borrOWers after a loan contract is accepted, collateral ceases to be a screening device to screen Out the em cient borrowers from the inefficient. Technically T1 establishes that in this mode], the 56 zero-profit, curves of the banks are steeper than the indifference curves of the borrowers: wlliCh violates the necessary condition for the existence of a separating eqUflib’ium' What this means is that in spite of the the bank having an additional instrument in the form of collateral, it still cannot have perfect control. It is not possible for the banks to 013 in this Case, can“ separate out the corrupt firms from the non-corrupt firms Collateral, n behind this result is be used as a self—selection device by the borrowers The intUltiO oweI‘S put that collateral is akin to “monitoring Costs” in this model. BY making the b0“ S Of both in all their weaIth as collateral the banks are ensuring that the emreprene“I T311 banks types put in maximum efTOrt after the Contract is accepted. By taking collate try to solve the moral hazard issues which arise in the credit market. . . QfiSid‘eYEd Thus, in this model where both adverse selection and incentive effects at u . . “0‘, be Simultaneously, exxs‘tence of private Signalling in a separating equilibrium 5 not, selve possible. Collateral is used by banks to solve moral hazard problems _ it doe as a screening device to screen Out the corrupt firms from th e non-corrupt The Ollly equlllbfium which exists in this economy is the complete pooling equil’b ' l r .1th , Where only one type of a bank contract is offered to everybody, Pooling Equilibrium : The solution to this pooling equilibrium is gi Veh b 5’ C211}. T = it? +(1+ mu; —— [(Y + (1 + (3)112)? + 4(fiw(1 — Y ~ w) _ ml} where Y E Yp — 7(Yp _ YL). OIIQ e we have established that no separating equilibrium can exist the solution t l ’ O t 1e 57 pooling equilibrium follows the same logic as given in the Full information case (3) and (4). However, since the banks are not aware of the actual yields that the entrepreneurs get from the project, they have to offer the contract on the basis of the average Yield . . , . ture that the perceive in the economy, depending Upon the .7, or the 50031 infrastruc d by the banks' parameter. So, Y is the average productivity in the economy as perceive . . . - he Full The reason for taking mammum collateral (C = 10) remains the same as given in t . . . . - Stage information case, where Since loan applications can be rejected by the banks 111 III, therefore in equilibrium, no applications with c < 11) will be forthcoming - n 5 . - hen Ewe For ease Of comp utation WLOG assume 5 = 1. The Pooling equilibrium ‘5 t by \‘2 .8l C5111). (2.9) r = Erna—ire 4 41 2 + 111—12}. 3", the average yield of the prOject in the economy, is defined as befor . o. 2-4 Social Infrastructure and Credit Ration - We now introduce another form of heterogeneity in the model We assu . me t L - ' T», . - . at "‘diVid‘ ld-ls differ lIl wealth (W). 1118 llCtel ogcnmty 15 ObSCIVablc and diflcrcnc '08 in t} 10 WC' dlth of borrowers is public knowledge. We assume that the wealth is distrib t d 1381‘ a s H < 1 is the necessary condition for 3 Of a separating equilibrium in a risk neutral enviroiim,ent Pr 1 13' ' ‘ ' - . Q of T1 Slows that even when [3 E (. 9 1) a poolm ecui] of g l ibrium pareto dominates. Therefore We Call 355111118 [l = 1, WLOG. C'd'f F(w) We retain the a‘SSUInptiOII Of all wealth being used as collatera/in borrowing- Lendel‘s can now 013551” borrow” as per risk, on the basis of an Observable indicator, the wealth they have to pOSt as collateral. Given that collateral is positively associated with effort. (and negatively associated With risk), the banks Classify the poor borrowers to he riskier than the rich borrowcl‘S- This Classification determines the interest rates that will be Charged to each class. We also get the familiar result[10] that the interest rates in this economy are negatively related to the wealth that can be posted as collateral. There exists credit rationing in this economy, such that all borrowers below the critical wealth group 10* do not have access to credit. We Car) Show th f mowing [proof in the e o v appendix]: P1 In a pooling equilibrium in the credit market, the 3 Qcial infrasthWTe of the economy determines the critical 212*, which defines the extent of credit rationing in this economy. The intuition is straight forward - given the Social infrastructure p ararn t 8 er 7 of o n e an economy, collateral is used then in monitoring the effort exerted by the . . n9111‘s 1n such an economy. Entrepreneurs posting more collateral are seen to b e Safer I'iSkS ) i Frespective of their actual returns from the project and are charged lower in t Brest 1'8, 1563. (7) also determines the critical wealth group wt (calculation in the appendix) W which no lending will be done by the banks. All borrowers having Wealth less t} K lax] wt irrespective of their actual yield from the project, Will be rationed fr Om the credit market Tl‘lis will occur in spite of the fact that lending is SOCially Optima], It is Perceived b Y the })E\1*1k8 that lending to this group does not make the banks brealoeVeIl at any interest rate. 59 10* is a function of the sociaI lllfl‘astructme index of the econOmy 7, Higher the value of this parameter, greater- will be the proportion of the population that will be barred from the credit market. A high ’7 means that a greater proportion of firms have to indulge in bribery and other unofficial payments - this indicates the quality of the social . ref - infrastructure In the economy. The ore, Elven a distribution at wealth in the economy, the extent, of credit rationing is greater When the Social infrastructure oi the economy is Poor (7 is high). The banks will then play safe by lending Only to the wealthier groups having Sufficient collateral. This is ShOWn in the diagram below Wh th . t rest rates ere e m e in the economy are negatively related to the amount of Wealth DOSt d llateral given e as CO 1 the economy’s social infrastructure indicator present in 7, W ith a decrease in 7’ and thereby an increase in )7, there iS a Shift Of this curve to the left F . en distribum“ - or a glV 'Y decreasing / Figure 5: Infrastructure and Credit Rationi n of wealth, lower the 50031 infra‘Sthture Parameter 7, both the cost of funds 7' and w', the critical wealth level below Which borrowers are barred from borrowing, is reduced- The extent of credit rationing 0f borrowers below a 112* thus depends upon the social inf-1'35tr ucture indicator of the economy, 2.4.1 Effect of a decrease in the Parameter ’7 From the section above it is now easy ‘50 COHCIUde about 3 the (3 ect. . . n , fl , s of policy (lI'IVC initiatives which reduce ’y, the proportion of firms who have to t . l resor to unofHCIa Pa3‘ ments and corruption, viz. the size of the ‘shadow’ or unoffici a] economy. e see that a, with a decrease in the parameter '7’ the COSt Of borrowing in is reduced the economy . Therefore, this result suggests that economies ranking low on t 1’1 . dex would Q corruptiOn ‘“ also be able to obtain funds at cheaper rates than those econQ 1'68 which are plagued by corruption and rent seeking act1v1t1es. (b) There is also an “entry” effect, related to the extent of Cr am With the decrease in 7, the cut off 111' is reduced, 3' .Y- "Ice rationing is a possible outcome in many models of asymmetric . "If . b - ' ' ' h f corr t’ ' - Canal: ~ [V6119 1111:), 15 made severe in t e presence 0 up Ion, meffiClencieS . 1012 111 j ’ £71. ”In 18 . , , . '. , I .00. . IQWS: and all those factors Wthl'l hamper the firms from Con duCting t $173th 5191‘ 6261‘ . O elr I] 0 1" T1 1erei0fe policy initiatives to reduce 7 will ameliorate the degree Of ere . eSseS SL1 Q11 economies. These results are important because they suggest that as as), me 61 mOdelS about the credit market are made more realistic to include a range of information asymmetries the Scope for pI‘iVate signalling is reduced. Public Signals in the form Of laws and regulations, infrastructure, and the quality of bureaucratic services will then be increasingly used to determine the extent 0f investment in an economy. The relevance of such public signals lies in the fact that in an imperfectly informed worm, they expand the information set that is available to the economy. 2.5 Conclusion The aim of this paper was to prov1de one among the many possible explanations to for investrnent common query: What are the reasons levels bfiing higher in a country . . a country like Bangladesh? I . - llke Smgapore as compared to the tried to explain this . . t t f as mmetric information in the credit . Within the con ex 0 Y arket, It iS fairly clear that as asymmetric models are made more complex to inclu 8 both . and moral hazard, the possibility a pooling equilibrium and t1) adVerse SBiBCthIl e reby Cred ‘ . - h ’ equilibrium increases. In thlS paper I also S Ow that m the rose t [atlbnin . “Ce 01“ gm layered asymmetric information structure, private signals can 005 get; 0 b I" use a [DU/t1; Will 1,,» a greater reliance on public Signals. An effimcnt legal a . nd Judi" smoothly functioning bureaucracy, good quality Of Public serviceS “1&1 . a 531le 1‘ ‘ , . 1k “irregular payments” t . . ”Jen {111115 are not compelled to ma e 0 get the” t c . - - ' heir smooth functioni ' , ’ fir 91.1}31'10’ ludicators which underlle t 11g. It IS fdctor e S like tilese arQ increasingly defining the lending and investment decisions of today 8’ hlch . . lllgapOre .1 s ' O I V able to I) ublicly signal its intentions to investors. The same cannot be S end about. Bangladegl ‘ i. 62 Z-A Appendix: 1. Proof of T1: The slope of the indifference curves in the r — c plane is given by totally differentiating Uii a which is given as follows, Uii 2 (Y; ‘ Ti + C-)2 N _ 2 Ci 515 2 W dci(borrowe1"3) (K ‘ 7}- + Ci) ‘< 0. Since (3”, _ 7-,. + Ci), we know is the equilibrium probability f 0 success of the pr0j eCt denoted as p“, and p" < l- The isorevenue curves of the banks is given by Rb : p‘ri + (1 — Pvflc, dr 2e EC—(banks) : % BR 613* 7: = ac (7" “ ‘3‘”) + (1 ‘ 10W? > o * V aRb 6p * . ,6 e 0 ET :2 01‘ (Ti _ laci) +p % 0 SZnCe ap‘ ( 7 1). am) ' i < 0 ‘5; > 0 sz (Ti — fiC-i) < p” , iff 1 >fi>""” >0 C1: Which puts very stringent conditions on the returns from the i, . \qz‘ 2(ri __ Ci) < K < (2ft ~ Ci) Q iVen the above, there is an additional condition on 5, (2.10) , 'r~— “ 1>r3>' p Efi’ Ci (2.11) 63 ' ' 'ons on Y'- Given the two concht1 ' and 5' above, we will have the isorevenue curve of the banks negative in the H: Space- dr‘ dc (ban/CS) =—W}l 2.12 p, g (a g M < ) Given that both the indifference curves 0f borrowers and the isorevenue curves of the banks are negative in the r-C Space’ the necessary condition for the existence 0i a sepa— rating equilibrium is that dr dc /""/ (banks) dc (boy‘rmers) (2.13) i.e. the indifference curves of the bOITOWGTS ShOUId be Steeper 1 th the 1n t 1e r—c space an isorevenue curves of the bankS- d7"! = 1‘ p" dC (borrowers) p‘ E: = fiflp—P)+(7‘i~,ec dc (banks) - (r-— —,6N We new show that 2.13 above cannot be satisfied. Taking th terms, we see that p" — (Ti " BCi) < 19.7 Therefore, the I1 existence of a separating equilibrium depends upon the value 0 the 12 (11,870,) [01‘ tile Q the termS- Which is, (11” 3(1—P’)+7‘i—5Ci < 1‘19 [3 < W (l‘pt)‘Ci VVQ know (1 _ p“) _ 7.1, < 0’ since r.- is the gross interest rate and theref0 Ore > 1 t Elkil’lg the denominator of the RHS, we now have to consider two p herefOre OSSlbiliti es, (1 mu 64 Ci 2 0- if (1_p‘)—q>0 2:} fl<0 if (1_p*)—q<0 ==> fi>1 (since l1_pi,n\>\1-pi—cil) Which is a contradiction to our assumption A 3- Therefore, even ii the isorevenue curves of the bank turn out to be negative in the r—c Space, a separating equihbtium cannot exist as they turn out to be steeper than the indi fl’erence curVes of the borrowers I II. Proof of P1 3 22:1 1 _N 8w (Y+4w —4):1>' (2.14) In order to prove that g:- < 0, we have to show the following , 0 < Y + 4w — 4 < 1. (2.15) Note that from the definition Of T given in (7): we have Y+4w—4 E l7~ 2(r— 20) Y n 20" ..... w) > 0, which follows from the proof of T1. And ,t of A OHOWS f p‘ thatO 0, Therefore the critical point of credit rationing gets lower With a reduction in the parameter 1 I 66 Chapter 3 Financial Constraints - ture and InfraStruc 0') What do firms have to say. 3.1 Introduction I tron I - ' 's an . . 11 and p Oductwrty 1 5 11k between infrastructure p OVISIQ r ' 1i 5 t s g hat there an ' linkages between in f t However, the prec1se estabhshed ac . rod“ . . are x Y . ts. d ctivit 0f infiaSthture In CS 1116“ u to CSfiifia ing the pro The emphas . ro econometric studies (using both time series :nd Cro ac - . these m ‘ at “credible” measures of the impact 0 lnfi. On amvmg 1 Productivity and growth. eConomic studies in the US and other developed e00 time-series Most 001221.68 f t m on infrastructure deVCIOpment This ‘ rates 0 re u Startli 11eg high I ggest 4 . Man StUdies re many cases (Gramlich, 199 ) y ' tion 1n Overéstlma u rtp bliC Seetor bstantially greater impact on private Sector Outpu su t as having t t ivate r uld bet two- 6c t. he reasons for this overestimation co t stmen ‘l' S Q ““16 fold: (a) Missing 1 pment Report, 1994 does a succinct summary of the various eStimates 1 1m The BOx 67 factor explaining trends: There COUld be a common factor that causes changes 1.” b0 t1; infrastructure and the output that needs to be included. Gramlich in his review essay cited abOVe suggests that gasoline Prices which led to both, a reduced demand for traCtors/trucks and thereby a reduced demand for highways and to a lower output in the 1970’s should be factored into this link. (b) Reverse Causality: Another important CO“Gem has been endogeneity and the direction of causality between infrastructure and output. While infrastructure may affect productivity and output, economic growth can also shape the demand/supply of infrastructure services which could lead to the OVBI'estimation of the returns to infrastructure. While common trend is a potent problem in the studies which use time-series data, the cross section studies do arrive at more SenSible measures ranging from an implied rate of return equal to the rate of return on Pfi" Elte investment (on the higher side) to zero (on the lower side). But cross section data 3150 i s not immune from the problem of reverse causality. In addition, in the cross section Studi es heterogeneity is another problem. There could be an overstating of infrastructure imp acts by confounding intrinsic state/nation productivity differences with the variation in infrastructure capital. Taking state level data for example, because prosperous states W0111d tend to spend more on public capital, there will be a positive correlation between State specific effects and public sector capital (Holtz-Eaken, 1994). However neither the time series not the cross sectional studies explain the mechanisms through which infrastructure affects growth. Unless such “micro” links between infrastructure and grOWth are uncovered — it will be difficult to understand the complex aggregate 1'61 ationship. Thus these results suggest two kinds of agendas for future research in this area; (a) detangling the endogeneity and heterogeneity issues econometrically using more 68 disaggregate data and (b) making the microeconomic linkages between pro‘mbn of in frastrucmre and the nature of the production process more precise. It will b e (new to know how other variables that affCCt growth work through infrastructure. This paper tries to fill the gap as regards agenda (b) by using disaggregated nation Wide firm level data based on the World Bank Business Environment Survey (WBES, 2000). It tries to show how infrastructure can crucially affect the ease with which firms can obtain finds from the capital market. The theoretical underpinning of this link is baSed on the analysis of public inputs in the context of asymmetric information, where infraStructure provision is seen to reduce the heterogeneity among firms. This reduction in heterogeneity has a crucial impact on the capital market, which is besieged by impfil‘fect information. Infrastructure is seen there to reduce the costs of asymmetric infoKination and improve the equilibrium in the capital market. Regarding empirical studies on these infrastructure-financial sector linkages, there hav e been some cross-country studies bringing out the link between infrastructure and the fitlancial sector. Cross-national studies considering the impact of infi'astructure on differences in the FDI flows (Globerman / Shapiro, 2002) find that FDI inflows respond Positively to good governance infrastructure and human capital. In a more detailed study regarding physical infrastructure and capital flows, Mathias Hoffman (2003) shows that di fferences in information and transport technology is able to explain cross country Variations in FDI and debt positions of countries . Sectoral studies focusing on rural in fiastructure’s impact on the local economy in certain developing economies have re\Iealed more about the infrastructure — financial sector linkages. Studying data over time from 85 districts in 13 Indian states, researchers found that improved 69 communications (through roads) lowered the banks’ COStS 0f ‘10ng busineSS Banks expanded lending to farmers and thereby increased farm output (Binswangef, et 31’ 1994). This study differs from the above in several ways. It uses firm-level data to Capture the link between infrastructure provision and financial constraints. The data is qualitative, based on the responses given by firms to questions regarding the difficulties faCBd by them with respect to infrastructure provision and obtaining finance. Using this Slime), data from some 10,000 firms spread across 80 countries (The World Bank usiness Environment Survey, 2000) this study tries to capture the nexus between these infi‘aStI'uctural and financial constraints facing firms. Using both Ordered logit and Ordered Probit estimates, it concludes that taking care of all region specific and firm Speci fic differences, firms facing high infrastructural constraints are most likely to face high financial constraints as well. More specifically, this link is seen to be stronger in the case of (i) firms in low income, developing countries as compared to high income dev eloped countries (ii) smaller sized firms as compared to the larger firms. 3.2 Data and Methodology The World Business Environment Survey (WBES 2000) was administered by the World Bank in roughly a parallel fashion to enterprises in 80 countries and one territory thl‘oughout the world, as basis for making regional comparisons of investment climate and the business environment conditions. The World Business Environment Survey (WBES 2000) is a survey of over 10,000 firms in 80 countries that examines a wide 1"ange of interactions between firms and the state. Based on face-to-face interviews with 70 firm managers and owners in late 1999 and early 2000, the WBES 8mm measurements in such areas as cOrI'Uption, judiciary, lobbying, investment 01inl ate an d the quality of the business enviroflInent. This survey thus tried to capture the my perceptions of key constraints in the business environment. Among the constraints faced by the firms were those relating to (a) Finance and (b) Quality of public services. Finance was the second leading constraint for most firms. At least 50% of the firms in all eVeloping regions cited financing as a serious constraint, only 40% of the firms in 015C D countries found it to be so. Finance as a constraint was more important to the SIhall and medium enterprises in the survey than to the large enterprises. Another key dim€>erlsion of the business environment was the quality of public services. WBES exPlQred both the overall efficiency of the government in delivering services and the quality of individual services. Nearly two thirds of the firms in Central Europe, Latin mefica and CIS countries and nearly 60% of the firms in South Asia report that 30" ernment is inefficient in delivering services. To get an idea of this nexus, table 1 shows the correlation between financial cgtlstraints and infrastructure constraints. Taking the subset of private, domestic firms (State owned firms and foreign firms were dropped out) it is seen that while 35% of firms fElcing no infrastructural constraints reported they had no financial constraints too, while OIlly 7% of the firms facing major infrastructural constraints reported that they no fillancial constraints. A test of the null hypothesis using Kendall’s tau-b that financial Constraints and infrastructural constraints are independent was rejected.2 The Kendall’s taill—b was more significant when this test was done disaggregating the data by firm size. \ 2 _Kendall's tau-b = 0.2441; Kendall's score = 3654854; SE of score = 157568.200 (corrected for t1€28); Test of Ho: gcf and infr are independent; Prob > |z| = 0.0000 (continuity corrected) 71 Small sized firms showed a stronger correlation betWeen infrastructure and fame. I 1a Constraints as compared to the medium sized or larger firms. Table 1; Correlation between Financial constraints and Infrastructure constraints general | constraint - | general constraint - infrastructure finance | no obstac minor obs moderate major obs l “~~__ ____________ + ____________________________________________ + _______ no obstacle | 671 218 146 77 | minor obstacle | 319 401 254 109 | moderate obstacle | 414 579 524 252 | major obstacle | 530 619 650 633 | “-~ __ ____________ + ____________________________________________ + ....... Total | 1934 1817 1574 1081 | Pearson chi2(9) = 799.3153 Pr = 0.000 l3j~1 chi2 = 0.0000; 0% likelihood = -4047.7911,~ pseudo R2 = 0.0735 gcf | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] ‘ ‘_ ————————— + ————————————————————————————————————————————————————————— cQ‘untryl [.4318122 .08244 5.24 0.000 .2702328 .5933916 QQ‘untryz I .353737 .0630527 5.61 0.000 .230156 .4773181 qgov_d [.1161673 .0407323 2.85 0.004 .0363335 .1960011 ngi_d I .06682 .0475951 1.40 0.160 -.0264647 .1601047 inf1_d I .1088632 .0474302 2.30 0.022 .0159017 .2018248 txreg_d .3476044 .0525174 6.62 0.000 .2446722 .4505365 gcorr_d| .2406343 .0434523 5.540 0.000 .1554694 .325799 tgdnLregdl .1709161 .0447298 3.82 0.000 .0832473 .2585849 81261 .2976406 .0696898 4.27 0.000 .1610512 .43423 81262 |.2424178 .0669084 3.62 0.000 .1112797 .3735559 lnvsal I .0030652 .0108683 0.28 0 778 - .0182363 .0243668 lnvfas |.0135233 .0111458 1.21 0.225 -.0083221 .0353688 lnvdebt I-.024300 .0078258 -3.11 0.002 -.0396385 -.008962 fn_re |-.000853 .0005122 -1.67 0.096 -.001857 .0001506 sal_d [- .037877 .0528281 -0.72 0.473 -.1414185 .0656638 Sa1f_d |-.021899 .0546672 -0.40 0 689 -.1290451 .0852465 inv_d |-.124489 .045451 -2.74 0.006 -.2135713 -.0354066 ihvf_d [.0746657 .0485123 1.54 0.124 -.0204167 .169748 1ab_d |.0570087 .044256 1.29 o 198 —.0297315 .1437488 labf_d \ .0132834 debt_a \ .2412359 debt} \ .1342956 \ -.064562 | .3772739 [“90 obstacle | nwlnor obstac | mofierate obs | aJO]: obstac I Pr( Pr(_cut1% .0812925 2 5% .1130827 5 0% .1593029 7 5% .2067256 9 0% .2321494 95% .2374023 9 9% .2387057 Percentiles 3.% .1613007 5% .2018408 Pr(gcf==1) Smallest .0085028 .0111069 .0113076 .0114367 Largest .6491151 .6966723 .6983643 .7171385 Pr(gcf==2) Smallest .0291266 .0354702 .0359377 .0362371 Largest .2387582 .2387586 .2387588 .2387591 Pr(gcf==3) Smallest .0963894 .1045309 74 Obs Sum of Wgt. Std. Dev. Variance Skewness Kurtosis Obs Sum of Wgt. Mean Std. Dev. Variance Skewness Kurtosis 3382 3382 .1486163 .1181638 .0139627 1.44125 5.047452 3382 3382 .1577637 .0550815 .003034 -.1749869 1.907029 10% .2274336 '105271 Obs 3382 2 5% .2650309 . 1264649 Sum of Wgt. 3382 5 0% .2979814 Mean .2847372 Largest Std. Dev. .0388117 '7 5% .3158797 .3212062 590% .320386 33212062 variance .0015064 95% .3209755 .3212062 Skewness -1.374217 99% .3211944 .3212062 Kurtosis 4.538319 Pr(gcf==4) Percentiles Smallest 1% .0618846 .0222005 1 5% .1249089 .0252547 250% .1678479 .0255418 Obs 3382 % .2765617 .0344667 Sum of Wgt. 3382 50% .4135177 Kean .4088827 7 Largest Std. Dev. .1745411 5% .5435668 .7994395 90% .6400273 .8006518 Variance .0304646 95% .6916173 .8025514 Skewness -.0359967 99% .7545248 .8291127 Kurtosis 2.169749 Tap le 3: Ordered Lo it Estimates on the General Financial Constraints c facin \Pr1Vate/domestic firms (V1883, 2002) ‘Nutrfflber’of obs = 3367; LR chi2(24) = 637.53; Prob > chi2 = 0.0000; Log likelihood = -4050.1943; Pseudo R2 = 0.0730 gcf | Coef. Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] \ - __________ + _________________________________________________________ ‘=‘=>untry1 I.7526405 .1378575 5.46 0.000 .4824448 1.022836 5391.111th I.5926867 .1040164 5.70 0.000 .3888182 .7965552 qgov_d I.2097505 .0682455 3.07 0.002 .0759917 .3435092 gcpi_d I.1136429 .0797983 1.42 0.154 -.0427588 .2700447 infl_d I.1775468 .0794326 2.24 0.025 .0218617 .3332319 t:xreg_d I.5747604 .0882174 6.52 0.000 .4018574 .7476633 Qcorr_d I.3910674 .0731885 5.34 0.000 .2476206 .5345141 t1!:thn_regd|.2767492 .0751361 3.68 0.000 .1294851 .4240132 sizel I.4979607 .1162416 4.28 0.000 .2701315 .72579 81262 .4163502 .1116201 3.73 0.000 .1975788 .6351216 lnvsal I .0029228 .0182491 0.16 0.873 -.0328449 .0386904 lnvfas I.0232014 .0187301 1.24 0.215 -.0135089 .0599117 JLlfrvdebt |-.038626 .0132012 -2.93 0.003 -.0645 -.012752 fn_re I-.001455 .0008634 -1.69 0.092 -.0031471 .0002372 sal_d I-.038096 .0890218 -0.43 0.669 -.2125754 .1363837 sa1f_d I-.048070 .0918659 -0.52 0.601 -.2281242 .1319836 inv_d I-.231266 .0765298 -3.02 0.003 -.3812618 -.0812706 invf_d I .110892 .0815559 1.36 0 174 -.0489547 .2707386 lab_d I.08773'75 .0740175 1.19 0.236 -.0573341 .2328091 75 Liz" labf_d \.0292579 '0745322 0 39 0.695 — .11687'75 .1753932 debt_d I.4010898 ° 07 4 6 5.14 0.000 3432204 ~5539592 debf_d 1-2233626 $785 ‘4 2.84 0.004 $594183 .37730 1n£r_d I.6261608 .0717253 8.73 0.000 ~435531 '7 33739 _________ +____________---_;1 ‘___-__-_____________---__ ‘ ---_ - 567393 cum I .3430544 05876 (Ancillary ------ ~ cut2 I 1.396923 2066047 parawneters) cut3 I 2.765965 2106662 gcf I Probability "BL-8;};a -\ \ ---------- ............. +___-_-----—--—— - - - ~ ~~------__-__ -____ no obstacle | Pr( xb+11<_CUt1) 0 1491 minor Obstac | Pr(_Cut1 ch12 = 126.28 Log likelihood = —1380.5618 Pseudo R2 7 8.0000 ‘ 0437 f Coef. Std. Err. z p) ------------- ~ _____ g""95% Cour. Interval, count 1 '08091416 02357151 3.43 0.001 . ------------ _ count::2 |.5023055 .1956456 2.57 0.010 .ii;;::; 1'271135 qgov_d |.1802941 .1163144 1.55 0.121 -.O47678 '8857637 1nf1_d |.1799364 .1365316 1.32 0.188 --0876505 '4082553 txreg_d |.2681226 .1739174 1.54 0.123 -.0727493 '4475334 gcorr_d |.5235881 .1210447 4.33 0.000 ~286344a '3232332 tadm_xegd|.3078607 .1291084 2.38 0.017 .0548129 :5609085 81201 |.6100626 .177939 3.43 0.001 .2613085 .9588167 31292 |.4637863 .1701533 2.73 0.006 .1302921 .7972305 lnvdebt |-.017755 .0075727 -2.34 0.019 -.0325974 —.0029129 fn_re |-.001653 .0014582 -1.13 0.257 -.OO45108 .0012051 inv_d |-.141776 .1176203 -1.21 0.228 -,372307 .0887561 debt_d |.3649487 .1289211 2.83 0.005 .1122679 .6176294 deb£_d |.2920326 .1265891 2.31 0.021 .0439225 .5401‘25 __ ___________ + _________________________________________________________ _Cutl I —.658983 .3449017 (Ancillary parameterSl _cut2 1 .5433287 .3399581 _cut3 1 1.89135 .344221 gcf I Probability Observed \ \_. ---------- +_ ____________________________________ 130 obstacle I Pr( xb+u<_cut1) 0.0742 Ithz‘knor obstac | Pr(_cut1 ch12 : . 1 Log likelihood = —2712.32‘43 Pseudo R2 7' g 0000 -------------------------------------------- ‘ 0619 Std Err. “““““““““““““““““ gcf | Coef. z P> z “ ------------ -+”--”“”“'"’3;"‘““----—----1_1_____£?§% Conf_ Interval] 3 .173 58 3 91 --------------- comm—1:1!1 l-5794“ - 0.000 .3392555 ‘ countryz |.6161416 .120823: 5.10 0.000 .3793327 1.019677 “and \.259 5773 .08323 3.12 0,002 .0964303 .8529505 in£1__d \.220 8901 .0912711 2.42 0.016 .0420”; .4227244 txreg_d \.697 3715 .100352 6.95 0.000 .5005353 .3997731 gcorr__d \.3493381 .0883 3.96 0.000 .1762732 -8940577 tadn regal .2763815 .0914586 3.02 0.003 .0971259 '522403 3712.1 \ .430622 .1461425 2.95 0.003 .1441331 455537 31292 .3915279 .1457874 2.69 0.007 .1057893 °Zl7055: 1nvdebt \-.o16495 .0057232 -2.88 0.004 -.0277122 - 6057;266 in re |-.001333 .0010599 -l.26 0.209 —.0034099 .000 778 “I”; |-.224072 .0843697 -2.66 0.008 -.3894337 -.05877:l4.47 debt_d .437958 .0948721 4.62 0.000 4.520121 .523”: _____________ +--------——-------—---———--_--______________________-___-_ cutl 1 .3813447 .2302995 (AnCillary parameters) cut2 1 1.394558 .2316537 cut3 | 2.770673 .2371747 -—— gcf I Probability Observed _____________ +————----—--—---—-—-—-——-——----———-___ no obstacle | Pr( xb+u<_cutl) 0 1923 minor obstac | Pr(_cut1