_ $3.3» .11....rf 4.94. .9955”... yuan. .4 d1... 4 ¥ n 9.5) .2131. a. k. I .5: 33s “5-1 5% x- ; [.4 z. 1 i In“ I. r. .14.. km. 1,4 01 . 4 . , tuna-«.53. f? a , V . :9. 5:43.33. :51. sigh—tum . .thvitfixd. :A n . , . .19.}: 5...: ‘ .fsu . ‘ , . . , 5,. i V . 5.... “Sudan. . ‘ v ‘ .‘ . .triinuuzs ‘ ‘. 3.. t .43.... f .1: .1 I. it. .2 Us: (I 23.32. .3." n... . .31! .l'... 3:30! ‘3 1 hv 47..., l. 1 1.. In}... .1. .23. x, L1 .92.}? F .. . 3.... ... . {xvii ,. to k x: :1 V I3?! it!!! u . I I. .0531! s. A . .. 11‘ an 1‘). .:I.. 99“ , )'l f, 1.. $3. \‘I d...‘ 21 . 3x: g , i .!._S:A§1 Jr: ‘3‘- : . 1.33 L... . I!!.:‘b-hf.e , . . ‘ 1. , ‘ 3?... 3... . ‘.\ . .Bl I’..u||.;~ h... . A . 1.. 55;: o [ mess I 700D This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Decentralization, Economic Voting, and Accountability in a New Democracy: The Case of Mexico presented by Paloma Bauer de la lsla has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Ph.D. degree in Political Science WW Major Professor’s Signature 5/4/2006 Date MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution .r LIBRARY Michigan State University - .-.--—.--a-.—--- PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 2/05 p:/C|RC/DateDue.indd-p.1 DECENTRALIZATION, ECONOMIC VOTING, AND ACCOUNTABILITY IN A NEW DEMOCRACY: THE CASE OF MEXICO By Paloma Bauer de la Isla A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 2006 ABSTRACT DECENTRALIZATION, ECONOMIC VOTING, AND ACCOUNTABILITY IN A NEW DEMOCRACY: THE CASE OF MEXICO By Paloma Bauer de la Isla The research question that motivates this dissertation is whether new democracies develop functional mechanisms of accountability. Taking economic voting as an indicator of electoral accountability and exploring the effects of decentralization on incumbent support, I examine under which institutional conditions electorates in new democracies might become economic voters. Employing both aggregate and individual level data, the dissertation explores hypotheses about economic voting at the subnational level in Mexico. The case of Mexico is particularly well-suited to study voters’ rationales in a post electoral authoritarian context, where state-level institutions are struggling to gain political and financial autonomy. The central argument is that the propensity of the electorate to become sophisticated and effectively hold elected representatives accountable is contingent upon state-level political and economic decentralization. I find that state-level factors exercise a powerful effect on electoral outcomes. Specifically, I demonstrate that state governments become more accountable to citizens with the increase of decentralization - measured by state-level financial autonomy and electoral competition. enj in)” him we at: Ln for int 3P Sil lllt f0] lri \l’ \\ Cl, ACKNOWLEDGMENTS It gives me pleasure to thank those who helped me in countless ways both to enjoy and to complete the writing of this dissertation. First and foremost, I am grateful to my advisor Mark P. Jones. I was very lucky to have a chance to learn from and work with him. I deeply appreciate his unconditional support, commitment, and confidence. These were essential to the successful completion of this degree. I am grateful for his guidance at every step, his common sense, and his friendship. As a graduate student in the Department of Political Science at Michigan State University, I had a chance to study with excellent teachers. I thank Dr. Michael Bratton for a three-year research assistantship. A challenging experience, the assistantship introduced me to African politics and allowed me to explore several political issues. I appreciate Dr. Bratton’s constant willingness to help. I also appreciate Dr. Brian D. Silver’s support throughout. His classes, at once challenging and fun, provided me with the requisite theoretical basis essential for the pursuit of my own questions. I am grateful for his advice and helpful suggestions. I have also been extremely fortunate to enjoy the friendship and support of former professors at other institutions. I thank Todd A. Eisenstadt of American University. I also thank Chris Reardon, Cliff Wirth, and Mark Wrighton of the University of New Hampshire. I value my friendship with Professor William Baker of the University of Maine and strive to emulate his example of excellence in teaching. This dissertation could not have been completed without the support and generosity of Alejandro Moreno and others at the newspaper Grupo Reforma. I am gratefirl for access to Reforma ’s pre-electoral surveys as these provide the basis for part iii of this study. I thank Eric Magar at ITAM (Autonomous Technological Institute of Mexico) for giving me access to ITAM’s library resources while I was doing field work in Mexico. Thanks are due to Carlo Angel Varela at Banamex (Banco Nacional de México) for important compilations of electoral data. I appreciate Jorge Hemandez’s extensive and careful help toward producing the macro-level data set. I am grateful for generous support of my doctoral studies provided by from the Center for Latin American and Caribbean Studies at Michigan State University. Finally, I thank my friends and family for their company, laughter, and encouragement. I am deeply indebted to Carina, my sister and best friend, whose unconditional support helped me in so many ways to attain this goal. My debt to my parents is without measure. I know my father shares with me this happy moment. Cl List of Tables List of Figures TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter 1. Introduction 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 Overview of the Argument Contributions Research Design and Data Case Selection Composition of Chapters Chapter 2. Theory 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 Introduction Dissertation’s Place within Democratization Literature Economic Voting Economic Voting in New Democracies Accountability and Decentralization in New Democracies Conclusion Chapter 3. The Mexican Case 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 Introduction The Hegemonic Party System Political and Economic Centralization Reform and Transition Rise of the Opposition Altemation and Divided Government The Mexican Voter Chapter 4. Aggregate-level Analysis 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 Introduction Theoretical Considerations Hypotheses Data and Model Analysis and Results Conclusion vii viii "OONQ-h-H 13 15 18 25 29 35 37 37 38 41 44 45 49 51 69 69 71 75 77 80 84 Chapter 5. Individual-level Analysis 5. 1 Introduction 5.2 Theoretical Considerations 5.3 Hypotheses 5.4 Data and Model 5.5 Analysis and Results 5.6 Conclusion Chapter 6. Conclusion Appendices Appendix A. States and Election Years, Chapter 4 Appendix B. Question Wording and Coding, Chapter 5 Appendix C. List of Mexican States Bibliography vi 9O 9O 91 96 98 102 105 117 122 123 125 146 147 I‘ in) ~ 1.] 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 4.1 4.2 4.3 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 5.7 LIST OF TABLES Research Design Ranney Index in Mexican States, 1972-1989 Ranney Index in Mexican States, 1990-2004 Holbrook-Van Dunk Index and Folded Ranney Index in Mexican States Experience under Non-PR1 Rule, Mexican States, 1985-2004 Diverse Indicators of Financial Autonomy in Mexican States, 2004 Gubernatorial Elections across Mexican States, 1985-2004 Local Legislature Elections across Mexican States, 1985-2004 Main Characteristics of the States Included in the Analysis Gubernatorial Approval, Selected Mexican States Vote Choice in Gubernatorial Elections, Selected Mexican States Vote Choice in Local Legislature Elections, Selected Mexican States Gubernatorial Approval in Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set Vote Choice in Gubernatorial Elections in Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set Vote Choice in Local Legislature’s Elections in Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set vii 12 61 62 63 64 86 88 89 108 111 112 113 114 115 116 b.) L’) (J) U! 1.1 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 4.1 5.1 5.2 LIST OF FIGURES Overview of the Argument State’s Revenues, 1970-2003 Number of Seats in the Chamber of Deputies, 1961-2003 Party Affiliation of Governors in the 32 States, 1980-2004 Experience under Non-PR1 Rule, Mexican States, 1985-2004 Holbrook-Van Dunk Index, Mexican States 1970-2004 Number of Seats in Local Congresses, 1974-2004 Distribution of Seats in Local Congresses, 1974-2004 Local Congresses where one Party has a Majority of seats, 1978-2003 Electoral Victories in MR Districts by Parties Other than PRI, 1974-2000 Total Votes for Incumbent Party, Gubernatorial Elections 1985-2004 State’s Own Revenues, Average Percentage 2000-2002 Mexican States, Own Revenues, Average 1989-2003 viii 11 59 60 60 65 66 67 67 68 87 109 110 Ill dc Chapter 1. Introduction The broad research question that motivates this dissertation is one of accountability in emerging democracies. Taking economic voting as an indicator of electoral accountability and exploring the effects of decentralization on incumbent support, I examine under which institutional conditions electorates in new democracies might become economic voters. Specifically, by exploring the effects of political and economic decentralization on incumbent support across the Mexican states, this study seeks to assess whether and to what extent electoral accountability is taking place in a new democracy. Does a new democracy guarantee electoral accountability? That is, does a new democracy develop those mechanisms of accountability necessary for voters to become, in the immortal words of V0. Key (1964:568), a “rational god of vengeance and reward”? Furthermore, do voters assign responsibility to the right level of government? Are voters able to correctly distinguish between national and subnational performance when voting at the state level? Without doubt, accountability lies at the bottom of these questions. Being a product of a number of institutional mechanisms, its importance for the success of any representative democratic regime cannot be overstated. Accountability is, however, not an immediate or automatic product of democracy, as democratic regimes can still exist without the adequate working of checks and balances that guarantee accountability (Bratton 1998). This is, I believe, an important shortcoming in some democratic regimes, and a potential danger for their consolidation, quality, and even survival. Nations where the essential democratic institutions are in place, but where accountability to its citizens is not guaranteed, lack clearly a major component of democratic life and risk developing serious problems of govemability. As argued by Rose, Mishler, and Haerpher (1998235), “if a regime is to be fully democratic, the government of the day must be accountable to the electorate.” By extension, a regime lacking accountability is in danger of losing its citizens’ support and satisfaction vis-a-vis the system. Eventually, a dissatisfied and angry civil society can end up alienating itself from the system through apathy, indifference, or even through violent means. Thus, the dangers to the democratic legitimacy, stability, and durability of the system are countless (Easton 1965). Accountability is, however, a complex issue to explore. With this research, I hope to shed light on this concept by looking at one specific component of democracy and one essential mean of accountability: elections. Elections represent the most direct link between citizens and the government, as well as the principal form of accountability. In fact, for many citizens in the world, elections are the only mechanism to connect with their government. The act of voting itself is critical in two major ways to ensure representation, accountability, and responsiveness to the citizens by political leaders. First, elections are the natural mechanism for citizens to hold their government accountable for its past performance (Schedler 1999). By voting based on a rational choice of whether to reward or punish the sitting government, voters are able to experience first-hand an act of governmental accountability. Second, the way voters elect their leaders greatly determines what kind of representation and the level of responsiveness they will experience from their government.l When a democracy fails to ' See Przeworski, Stokes, and Manln (1999). ensure its citizens that their political participation is meaningful,2 the durability and even viability of the system is put at risk. In other words, elections are the most straightforward mechanism of accountability in a democracy, and accountability is needed for a democratic regime to succeed. What is needed for elections to be an act of accountability? Following Dahl’s (1971) emphasis on contestation and participation, scholars agree on a number of factors, such as clean, periodic, and competitive elections; a competitive party system; and an interested, informed, and involved electorate. But what does it take to make these factors converge and make accountability work? Furthermore, assuming that the minimal institutional standards are in place, are citizens in a new democracy “ready” for democracy? Or, are citizens in such contexts less capable of being rational voters than citizens in old democracies? In this project, I argue that the decentralization of political and economic powers at the subnational level can lead to make institutional mechanisms of accountability work, such as elections. When a subnational government does not depend fully on the central government for resources and political power, then elections acquire a form of “local power” — that is, subnational politicians need their constituents’ electoral support and therefore elections are meaningful for a majority of voters. Thus, elections acquire different meanings, depending on the degree of decentralization attained in a given region, which will vary across nations, and more importantly in this work, even within a nation. In other words, those ideal results of decentralization that are argued to create 2 Specifically, by “meaningful” I mean here that voters know that with their vote (as a majority) they can cast a government out of office. h. dc cl eventually a sophisticated electorate, such as transparency, availability of information, and political knowledge, depend on the institutional context of a given state. The underlying logic of this argument is that electoral accountability can only exist, if those institutional arrangements designed to respond to citizens are functioning appropriately. This study addresses the specific question of whether the expected outcomes of political and economic decentralization reach the electoral arena. Ideally, decentralization is supposed to promote democracy at the grassroots level, developing hereby different mechanisms of accountability. Whether voters are able to use their voting right as an act to hold the government accountable remains an open question. 1.1 Overview of the Argument This study looks at an assumed and indirect outcome of decentralization, electoral accountability, by means of exploring electoral choice at the subnational level in a new democracy. Ideally, citizens living in a system with working accountability, make use of elections as one way of evaluating their representatives. Figure 1.1 shows a model of the argument that I develop in this dissertation. In the first place, effective decentralization can only take place when politicians need to take into account their constituencies for political support, and even survival. This happens when politicians depend no longer on the central government (or hegemonic party), but on local constituencies for their electoral support and political success. Effective decentralization of political and economic powers is then assumed to bring the government closer to the peeple, by delegating powers (political, fiscal, and/or administrative) to lower levels of government. This presumably creates, on the one hand, a cycle of greater clarity of responsibility in which there is greater flow of information. On the other hand, it raises the levels of pluralism, electoral competition, and a state’s financial autonomy vis-a-vis the central government. Altemation of power and divided governments are common at the subnational level. Overall, subnational units are more autonomous both politically and economically from the central government. This new institutional environment is expected to create changes in the governing style of subnational politicians, who depend increasingly on citizens’ evaluations to retain power. The increased transparency of information and responsibility increases citizens’ political knowledge and heightens their attention to public affairs. The result is a sophisticated electorate, who in turn is more likely to make an electoral choice based on performance evaluations. This, I argue, is a way of observing electoral accountability. This model, as applied to the case of Mexico, explores the impacts of political and economic decentralization on incumbent support across the Mexican states. Specifically, the focus of this study is on the relationship between two ideal outcomes of a decentralization process—namely, electoral competition and financial autonomy—and incumbent support at the subnational level. The overall purpose is twofold: In the first place, I aim to explore whether, and to what extent, decentralization impacts electoral behavior. By using macro-level data, I find evidence that both political and economic decentralization impact electoral behavior, specifically, economic voting, at different degrees. This leads to the second overall goal, which is to fiu'ther explore with micro- level data the existing variation across the states. The principal hypothesis leading this work is that as the level of decentralization intensifies, voters become more sophisticated and thus, hold the government accountable by voting based on a performance evaluation. Overall, I find support for this hypothesis. 1.2 Contributions This dissertation contributes to our general knowledge of the quality of new democracies in the following three ways. a) By exploring the subnational level of politics in a new democracy, where the transition process towards democracy started at this level of government, rather than at the national, like most other studies, this dissertation contributes to the understanding of different stages and paces of the transition and deepening processes of democracy within one nation. Mexico presents an excellent case for studying the evolution of democracy at the state and local levels, which in some states started approximately 20 years before it fully reached the national arena, while others have not experienced alternation of power until today. b) This study contributes to the broad field of economic voting, which remains placed high on the political science research agenda. The political importance and effects of economic factors sustain a lively scholarly debate that has plenty of open questions, particularly in reference to fragile economic and democratic contexts, where the study of economic voting is a particularly relevant exercise. Specifically, by exploring economic voting at the subnational level in a formerly hegemonic party system, this study contributes to evaluate the differing degrees of institutional capacity of subnational governments. c) The third contribution refers to decentralization, a public policy that has been extremely popular in emerging democracies across the world. However, so far, most of the literature has not spent much time on exploring the link between the expected accountability mechanisms resulting from decentralization and electoral outcomes. This dissertation contributes to the research program on decentralization by exploring the potential implications of decentralization on democratization policies from the electorate’s standpoint. 1.3 Research Design and Data This dissertation employs a subnational research design to study electoral behavior across the Mexican states. The research design, which I briefly will explain here is summarized in Table 1.1. I make use of both subnational- and individual-level analyses. First, look at the question of interest within a subnational level of analysis. For this, I gathered an aggregate data set composed of a collection of macroeconomic, fiscal, and electoral indicators spanning 34 years. This cross-sectional analysis allowed me to examine different hypotheses across the 31 Mexican states and the Federal District (Mexico City) over a significant period of time. The macroeconomic data is taken primarily from Mexico’s Institute of Statistics (Instituto Nacional de Estadz’sticas, Geografia e Informatica, INEGI). The electoral data and other socio-demographic indicators used in the dissertation were obtained from the Federal Electoral Institute (Institute Federal Electoral, IF E), Center for Research for Development (Centro de Investigacién para el Desarrollo, CIDAC), Banamex (Banco Nacional de México), and Mexico’s National Population Council (Consejo Nacional de Poblacién, CONAPO). SUI Rt 83 01 I; Second, I look at the question of interest within an individual-level analysis using survey-level data. The data used was collected by the Mexican newspaper group Reforma, and it is based on pre-electoral surveys collected in a sample of states. The sample of states reflects Mexico’s rich subnational variability, which raises the study’s generalization power. The surveys, based on face-to-face interviews, contain identical or highly comparable items, which allow both the comparability among the individual states and the use of a merged data set. 1.4 Case Selection In this dissertation, I use the case of Mexico to test hypotheses about the presence of rational vote decisions in new democracies. Mexico makes an excellent test case for four main reasons. a) Given that Mexico represents the prototype of a new democracy, the findings can be applied to a large number of contexts. By being a “prototype of a new democracy,” I mean that the political context in Mexico is similar to that of other new democracies. For instance, Mexican voters have been traditionally unable to distinguish between subnational and national politics. As is the case in most of Latin America and other regions of the world, the Mexican executive has counted with disproportionately much more power than the other branches of government, which made national politics much more visible to the eyes of the electorate. Within such a context, it is difficult for voters to assign responsibility to the appropriate layer of government. In Mexico, subnational politics developed in the shadow of a strong presidential system and a highly centralized system of relationships between the center and subnational units—a context that is not 111 Ct 11; Ill {11 dt (7 \\ uncommon in new democracies. Another trait of the Mexican system, which is shared by many other developing democracies, is that within the processes of transition and consolidation of democracy, both political institutions and civil society are struggling to become more autonomous and develop more power and credibility on their own. b) The rich variability across the Mexican states in terms of democratic experiences is very well-suited to explore the questions of interest, such as why some contexts within a nation are more prone to produce economic voters than others, and why some governments develop different styles of governing that favor the use of accountability mechanisms, while others still show traits of authoritarianism. In sum, Mexico presents an ideal laboratory because of its variations in electoral competition levels and overall degrees of decentralization. c) Recent and extensive use of decentralizing policies across most of the developing world call for checks on the performance of these measures. Mexico is especially well- suited to evaluate decentralizing efforts, because it is formally a federal system (among the three biggest in Latin America), which did not work as such during the one-party regime. Therefore, this study is particularly appropriate to evaluate the effects of recent efforts to decentralize power in a federal system. (1) Last, but not least, Mexico is an important case of study because of its obvious political, economic, and social importance within the region. Mexico shares with the US an array of issues, such as geographic proximity, economic relations, immigration, and security, among many others, which make it imperative to deepen our understanding of Mexico’s political development. 1.5 Composition of Chapters The dissertation is structured as follows. Chapter 2 consists of a review of the literature related to this research. The chapter states the theoretical perspective on which the arguments of this study are built. In Chapter 3, I present the case that will be used to test hypotheses in this project, Mexico. The subsequent chapters empirically test the argument of this research. Chapter 4 makes use of macro-level data to explore this research question across Mexico’s 31 states and the Federal District between 1985 and 2004, while Chapter 5 uses micro-level data in a sample of states. Finally, Chapter 6 presents the conclusions reached in this study and expands on how they might contribute to the comparative literature on electoral behavior. 10 Figure 1.1 Overview of the Argument Political and Economic DECENTRALIZATION Pluralism; Electoral competition; Altemation; Divided governments; States more autonomous from central government; State/local governments more Greater clarity of responsibility, transparency, and availability of information attentive to citizens’ needs Citizens with more political knowledge and interest in politics; Overall democratic character of population grows Greater political sophistication among electorate 1 Voter makes electoral choice based on perforrnance- evaluation of sitting government; Economic Voting ELECTORAL ACCOUNTABILITY ll Table 1.1 Research Design Level of Analysis Subnational Individual Data Aggregate Survey Dependent Variable: Incumbent Support (percentage of votes and seats in local congresses) Independent Variables: State-level economic performance, local financial autonomy, electoral experience under opposition, and political control variables Method: Cross-sectional analysis Sm: Own data set, most indicators from IN EGI Dependent Variables: Individual approval and electoral support for the incumbent party Independent Variables: Individual assessments of subnational and individual economies, and individual control variables Method: Individual-level survey analysis Source: Pre-electoral surveys, Reforma Chapter 2. Theory 2.1 Introduction In a democratic regime, elections are the most powerful instrument for citizens to express their preferences vis-a-vis the government. In this sense, elections serve as the most straightforward method to enforce accountability. However, does an electoral democracy3 guarantee electoral accountability? That is, does an electoral democracy develop those institutional mechanisms of accountability necessary for voters to hold elected officials accountable for their performance? Assuming that elections meet all requirements necessary to be classified as clean, open, periodic, and competitive, what makes voters take reasoned electoral decisions? What leadsto citizen circumspection in a new democratic regime? I argue that voters are more likely to make reasoned electoral choices when they perceive that their vote has a real chance of impacting the election either way, and that this can be achieved through appropriate decentralization of political and economic powers. Economic voting has been shown to be strongly dependent on a context of institutional clarity of responsibility,4 which can vary both between and within nations (Anderson 2000; Nadeau, Niemi, and Yoshinaka 2002; Pacek and Radcliff 1995; Powell and Whitten 1993). I argue that decentralization determines partly the extent to which a context of clarity of responsibility develops. Therefore, I want to explore whether, and to what extent, decentralization indirectly leads to economic voting. The principal 3 According to Diamond, Hartlyn, Linz, and Lipset (l999:x), an electoral democracy is “a civilian, constitutional system in which the legislative and chief executive offices are filled through regular, competitive, multiparty elections with universal suffrage.” 4 A term developed by Powell and Whitten (1993) to explain the variability of economic voting in cross- national studies in terms of the political context (or institutional arrangements) of a given nation. 13 hypothesis leading this work is that as the level of decentralization intensifies, voters become more sophisticated5 and are more likely to use elections as a mechanism of accountability. Furthermore, this might contribute to explain some of the uneven evidence of the theory found both across developing democracies and within individual nations. This chapter reviews the literature of economic voting, accountability, and decentralization within the broader literature on democratization. The objective of this chapter is, in addition to defining the major concepts as applied in this study, to lay out the theoretical framework on which this project is based on. The chapter is organized as follows. Next, I draw on the extensive literature on democracy to place economic voting, decentralization, and accountability in theoretical perspective. Second, economic voting is reviewed in both established and new democracies. Third, I define the concept of accountability as it is used in this project, and I discuss how decentralization is linked to elections as a means of accountability. Finally, the last section concludes with a number of testable propositions that link decentralization with electoral outcomes and accountability, and which will be empirically tested in chapters 4 and 5. 5 By sophisticated here, I mean that voters are able to punish or reward the incumbent administration when casting their vote at the subnational level. Throughout this dissertation, I equate sophistication with economic voting, regardless of whether it is prospective/retrospective or pocketbook/sociotropic. The general definition of economic voting followed here refers to the theory as a “reward-punish decision calculus on the part of the voter. The voter who feels better off financially (or sees the nation as a whole better off) will reward the incumbent Officeholder” (Atkeson and Partin 1995:99). According to this definition, I assume economic voting to be a “theory about applied rational, i.e. reasoning behavior” (Dorussen and Palmer 2002: l ); 2.2 Dissertation’s Place within Democratization Literature Since the “third wave” of democracy was unleashed in 1974, with the overthrow of the Salazar/Caetano dictatorship in Portugal, the number of democratic systems across the world increased in a dramatic way (Huntington 1991). Regardless of how one defines democracy,6 it is clear to most observers that the worldwide trend has been towards more democracy and freedom.7 Extensive scholarly work has both accompanied and followed up the development of democratic systems across the world. At first, this field of study was primarily concerned with questions on the conceptualization of democracy, such as defining democracy and fitting the different variants of democratic regimes into classifications of democratic regimes.8 Increasingly, more studies have turned to questions on the substance (or results) of democratic regimes, and a recurrent question refers to why some regimes succeed in their transition to democracy and eventual consolidation, while others fail somewhere along the way.9 This scholarly concern is clearly summed up by Diamond, Plattner, and Schedler in the following way: “Democracy, like so many objects of desire, is a moving target... now that these polities have reached democratic shores, often after years of intense struggle, they are discovering that they cannot just lean back, relax, and enjoy the democratic sun. Instead, they find themselves haunted by old demons that they had hoped to exorcise with democratic rule...” (l999:1). Broadly speaking, the literature on democracy and processes of democratization has focused on the study of political institutions and political actors. Scholars of political 6 See Diamond (1999) for different conceptualizations. 7 According to Freedom House (www.freedomhouse.or2), the number of “free” countries increased from 40 (or 25%) in 1975 to 89 (or 46%) in 2005. 8 See, for example, Collier and Levitsky (1997); Diamond (1999); Linz and Stepan (1996); Schmitter and Karl (1991). 9 For a recent study, see Diamond and Morlino (2005). 15 institutions have focused, for example, on comparing parliamentary versus presidential systems; on the nature of representation as a result of electoral systems; and on the overall institutionalization processes (e.g., Linz 1990; Linz and Stepan 1996; Mainwaring 1993; Jones 1995; O’Donnell 1994; O’Donnell, Schmitter, and Whitehead 1986; Shugart and Carey 1992). Scholars studying political actors, on the other hand, explore the extent to which political elites, parties, organizations, and citizens accept democracy as the “only game in town,” and the overall role of civil society in a democracy (e.g., Booth and Richard 1998; Putnam 1993). To a great extent, a democracy’s success in consolidating10 is a function of the balance reached between institutions and political actors. As Diamond and Chull Shin so clearly explain: “Democratic consolidation will advance to the extent that the political institutions of democracy are deepened and improved to become more open, responsive, accountable, and respectful of the law and to the extent that democracy is seen by the mass public to be delivering the political goods it promises: freedom, justice, transparency, participation, and a predictable, stable, constitutional order” (2000:21; italicized emphasis added). Without doubt, representation lies at the heart of the link between citizens and government. Scholars agree that in order to become consolidated, a democratic regime must succeed in developing legitimacy among political elites and citizens (Diamond 1999). Citizens are engaged when they participate according to the “rules of the game” of a democracy and when they know that their participation is meaningful to the system. As explained by Diamond, “at the level of the mass public, consolidation is indicated when ’0 A regime is consolidated when a) all political actors are constrained by the rules of the game b) majority of public opinion accepts legitimacy of democracy. Definition follows Linz and Stepan (1996) chapter 2, and Diamond (1999), chapter 3. l6 Ca) the overwhelming majority of citizens believe that democracy is the best form of government for their country at their time” (1999:68). However, as discussed by Bratton and van de Walle (1997:11-12), “...for ordinary people — in Africa as elsewhere in the world - the challenge of democracy concerns how to obtain accountability from officials of the state.” The quality of elections is one way of evaluating the extent to which political accountability is being institutionalized. However, “elections alone are not a sufficient condition of democracy” (Bratton and van de Walle 1997213). In this respect, Karl (1990) warned against the dangers of falling into an “electoral fallacy”—that is, equating elections with democracy. In fact, elections can still be held in regimes where systematic abuses of political rights take place. On the other hand, it is also “not sufficient for government to be responsive to citizen desires; citizens must also be able to hold government accountable” (Gomez and Wilson 20062127). Hence, elections can only be an indicator of a regime moving towards consolidation, when parties and political elites allow elections to serve the purpose of accountability and informed voters use elections in this manner. But, when does this happen? Voters will hold the government accountable only if they believe that the rules of the game are accepted and enforced, and that there are self-enforcing restraints on the government. That is, an electoral democracy meets partially the first requirement about the balance needed in the system to consolidate—that of working political institutions. Elections, in a liberal democracy,” remain the most straightforward mechanism of political participation, but beyond meeting the minimum requirements, they serve in a ” See Diamond (1999) on the distinction between liberal and electoral democracy. l7 broader meaning of representation, because political rights and civil liberties are guaranteed. In such a context, the democratic quality of citizens increases. A growing body of theoretical work and empirical evidence suggests that a vigorous civil society is instrumental, if not vital, to the consolidation of new democracies.12 Scholars have argued the manner in which civil society organizations and movements provide outlets of participation, and how such networks foster trust and cooperation—all of which leads to democratic consolidation. The institutionalization of elections, which link the government and civil society, lies at the heart of democratic consolidation. Ideally, beyond being open, free, competitive, and regular, institutionalized elections are used by voters to express preferences and evaluations. 2.3 Economic Voting One way to measure whether elections are serving as a mechanism of accountability between elected officials and citizens is by exploring how much voters actually reward or punish their governments when it comes to voting or expressing approval or disapproval towards the incumbent government. Indeed, this straightforward relationship between governmental performance and citizens’ evaluations has been developed as a barometer of institutional performance as seen through the eyes of the citizenry. As argued by Dorussen and Palmer, “economic voting is an instrumental act. Ideally, the electorate expresses at the ballot its preferences about proper management of the economy...Politicians who fail to heed the policy goals of the public, or who show a lack of competence in ‘managing’ the economy, are turned out of office. Economic ‘2 On civil society and democratic consolidation, see Diamond and Plattner (1994); Foley and Edwards (1997); Gyimah-Boadi (1998); Putnam (1993); Schmitter (1997). 18 voting thus constitutes a mechanism of democratic accountability” (2002:1-2). Drawing primarily on the experience of developed democracies, a large number of studies have demonstrated that governmental leaders and political parties are either punished or rewarded for their economic performance at the time of elections. The responsibility hypothesis, which in its simplified form states that “voters hold the government responsible for economic events” has driven the economic voting literature (Lewis-Beck and Paldam 20002114). This straightforward relationship has been extensively researched, producing hundreds of articles and books during the last decade.13 In fact, the field of economic voting remains one of the favorites among scholars to study voting models, partly because of the data availability and reliability, but also because efforts to test the theory have produced many other open questions. Overall, the theory lends itself to study electoral behavior from a wide array of angles. Economic voting refers to the basic following idea, which was articulated in 1978 by Tufte (65): “When you think economics, think elections; When you think elections, think economics.” In fact, this field began being articulated a few years earlier, when Kramer (1971) concluded that the fate of an incumbent president’s party depended largely on the state of the economy. This hypothesis was further developed on the basis of rational behavior theories, which basically argue that voters follow their self-interest and are capable of thinking rationally when casting a vote. That is, according to Downs’ Economic Theory of Democracy, voters act rationally in politics and seek to maximize their “utility income from governmental activity” at the time they make an electoral choice (1957237). Thus, according to the theory of economic voting, voters who base '3 For a complete review of the economic voting literature, see Lewis-Beck and Stegmaier (2000). 19 their vote choice primarily on their evaluations of the sitting government, are making a rational choice. Scholars of economic voting have been immersed in different debates over the exact dynamics underlying the voting calculus. For instance, at the aggregate level, questions revolve around which macroeconomic indicators best explain the relationship between economics and electoral outcomes. Other questions deal with the dimension voters use to evaluate their government (pocketbook versus sociotropic), or by the timeframe they consider (prospective versus retrospective). And yet another question refers to the layer of government that voters look at when they evaluate (national versus subnational). Despite these debates, however, there is an overall consensus in the literature supporting the link between economics and elections. In short, most scholars agree that the “economy matters” on election day. Next, I briefly review the evidence found in the American context and in other Western developed democracies. At the aggregate level, scholars who have explored the impact of macroeconomic performance on presidential approval or electoral outcomes, (e.g., Kramer 1971; Hibbs, Rivers, and Vasilatos 1982; Lewis-Beck and Rice 1992; Markus 1988; Norpoth 1984; Tufte 1978) argue that incumbent support is a function of its economic performance. Most studies using macro-level data usually link aggregate percentage support for the incumbent government with different macroeconomic indicators, such as unemployment, inflation, and economic growth rates. Although there is some disagreement in the literature as to which macroeconomic indicator has the most explanatory power, macroeconomic performance has been consistently found to be part of the voting calculus. 20 At the individual-level, researchers have explored the link between individual perceptions of the economy as a whole or their personal financial situation and vote choice or presidential approval (e.g., F iorina 1978, 1981; Key 1966; Kinder and Kiewiet 1979, 1981; Kiewiet 1981). Typically, micro-level studies include, in addition to the standard indicators of individual assessments of the economy, a number of socioeconomic and political control variables, such as income and education levels, and partisan identification. Within this line of literature, there are also a number of disagreements and unresolved questions but, despite them, scholars have found overall considerable evidence in support for the economic voting argument. The classic question of how citizens hold the incumbent government accountable for the performance of the economy has been answered in two main ways. On the one hand, the classic economic voting hypothesis presumes that voters assess their personal financial situation, or “pocketbook,” to make a vote choice. In fact, the pocketbook voting hypothesis lies at the core of the original theory underlying the economic voting literature. The idea that individuals “vote their pocketbooks” (Tufte 1978) originated in Downs’ (1957) research, who argued that voters make a rational decision when they vote by either rewarding or punishing the government, according to their personal experience and calculus on election day. However, results from the pocketbook hypothesis at the individual-level have been mixed or in some cases inconclusive (Fiorina 1978; Klorman 1978; Lewis-Beck 1988). These results have led other scholars to argue that individuals are more likely to be sociotropic rather than pocketbook voters. According to the sociotropic approach, voters tend to put more emphasis on the broader state of the economy in the country, rather than 21 dc re “'1'. ant Ma prn pri: focusing on their own personal financial well-being. For instance, Kinder and Kiewiet (1978, 1981) focused on the relationship between individual assessments of the general state of the economy and individual vote choice. Overall, they find that personal experiences are “politically unimportant” (19792522). That is, according to these authors, personal (economic) problems are important to citizens, but they do not expect the government to be responsible for solving these. On the other hand, Kinder and Kiewiet find that citizens do identify the broader, collective state of the economy as politically relevant. A different debate within the literature deals with the timeframe that voters use when they evaluate their governments. On the one hand, the classic economic voting hypothesis, following arguments developed by Downs (1957) and V.O. Key (1964), presumes that voters are self-interested and retrospective in nature. On the other hand, other scholars have put forward the argument that when individuals make a voting decision, they look at the prospects of the economy. That is, according to this line of research, voters evaluate the economy prospectively—they seek the option they perceive will benefit them the most in the future (Chappell and Keech 1985; MackKuen, Erikson, and Stimson 1992). The well-known terms of “banker” and “peasant” introduced by MacKuen, Erikson, and Stimson (1992), best illustrate the distinction between a prospective and a retrospective voter. According with this analogy, while a peasant pays primarily attention on his or her personal short-term circumstances, a banker focuses on the long-terrn horizon, being more sophisticated and objective in his or her decision- making process. With respect to the US, the authors conclude that “the electorate responds with the sophistication of the banker” (19922606). Again, despite existing 22 rh Il7c‘ ret~ disagreements, both approaches have found sufficient support in the literature (Lewis- Beck and Paldam 2000:114). Finally, yet another disagreement found in the economic voting literature, and one that is highly relevant to the question of democratic accountability, refers to whether the electorate is capable of assigning responsibility for economic performance to the appropriate level of government. That is, do electoral results at the subnational level of government respond to national economic and political trends rather than local conditions? Are the performance failures of subnational officials correctly punished by voters? The results of studies looking at both possibilities are mixed as well. According to the referendum-voting model, which lies at the heart of the economic voting theory, electoral outcomes are a result of the incumbent presidential administration’s performance. That is, the higher the approval ratings of the president (and/or the higher the levels of popular satisfaction with the state of the national economy), the higher the likelihood that the president’s party (or he himself) will be reelected. Consequently, state-level political leaders are not evaluated on the basis of their own performance, but rather on that of the president’s party. It is expected that, if the president’s enjoys positive evaluations, his party will benefit at the state-level, regardless of the specific performance of subnational politicians. Significant macro-level research applied to the American context suggests that voters see the President as solely responsible for national policy outcomes (e.g., Chubb 1988; Erickson 1989; Holbrook-Provow 1987; Peltzman 1987; Piereson 1975; Simon, Ostrom, and Marra 1991). On the other hand, scholars have found support for the argument that voters do look at state-level economic performance when they make a 23 0\ C21 Pa 1'65 511. for the SCI my, subnational electoral decision (e.g., Atkeson and Partin 1995; Lowry, Alt, and Ferree 1998). Micro-level data exploring this question has found mixed evidence as well. While some scholars find that voting in subnational elections reflects evaluations of national performance (Simon 1989; Stein 1990), other researchers have found that voters do distinguish between subnational and national policy responsibilities (e.g., Atkeson and Partin 1995; Carsey and Wright 1998; Howell and Vanderleeuw 1990; Partin 1995). Still other studies suggest that voters use a combination of national and state-level evaluations (King 2001; Svoboda 1995). As shown, despite the different debates taking place in the literature, there is an overarching agreement among scholars that identifies economics as part of the decision calculus. However, researchers who have reviewed the literature (Lewis-Beck and Paldam 2000; Nannestad and Paldam 1994) agree that the theory presents a problem of “spatial and temporal instability.” In other words, the problem with the theory is that results so far exhibit variability across countries, and even within countries over time. Still other scholars argue that the economic voting theory does a poor job in accounting for individual-level differences (Duch 2001; Gomez and Wilson 2001, 2006). Moreover, the instability problems of the theory are exacerbated when it travels to new democratic settings, where severe limitations to mechanisms of governmental accountability exist (for example, extreme centralization of powers, clientelist practices, or low levels of institutionalization of party systems), and the conventional economic voting model cannot be as widely generalized among the population as it is done in advanced democracies. The next section reviews the state of the economic voting literature in new democracies. 24 h: Cl 511 th’. \‘01 pril rel; EVE der pre all no do eCl 2.4 Economic Voting in New Democracies Are voters in new democracies as capable as those in established democracies to hold their governments accountable? Until recently, most studies had examined economic voting in the American context and Western European democracies. This is surprising on the one hand, given the obvious electoral importance that economic issues should have in those volatile contexts of the developing world. In fact, elections represent for many citizens in developing democracies the only opportunity to express their policy preferences. On the other hand, however, it is understandable to some extent that such studies did not focus on new democracies until recently, considering the common belief that electorates in these contexts are not “highly informed, policy-oriented economic voters” (Dorussen and Palmer 200222). Electoral behavior in new democracies has been primarily explained by factors such as ideological propensity, presence of patron-client relationships, or socio-demographic variables, rather than by voters’ performance evaluations. Voters in these contexts are easily assumed to lack the needed conditions to be critical voters, such as access to a free press. The applicability of the theory in new democracies is also constrained by the wide variation in political and economic contexts present in new democracies, in contrast with those of advanced democracies. Data availability and reliability have been a constraint as well in exploring economic voting in fledging democracies. But, as I detail in the next section, scholars of democratic development have increasingly applied the model to study citizen responses to the economy in new democracies. However, most of the evidence found so far is mixed or questions altogether the applicability of the model to nascent democracies. Next, I review a number of studies that have found clear evidence in support for the economic voting 25 ICI P0 prr tht' be lllt 01\ R11 theory, and then I mention studies that have found weak or no support at all for the theory. One of the early studies looking at the link between the economy and elections outside the context of established democracies was Remmer’s (1991) analysis of 21 presidential elections in Latin America. Looking at a time period dominated by the harsh regional economic crises of the 19805, Remmer finds an important relationship between economic conditions and vote choice. Also in Latin America, Seligson and Gomez (1989) find evidence in Costa Rica’s 1986 general election. More recently, Gélineau (2002) finds support for the theory looking at Argentina, Brazil, and Venezuela during the 19805 and 19903. Specifically, he finds that economic voting is contingent on the economic (e.g., inflation, unemployment) and political (e.g., reelection, degree of decentralization) contexts. In a cross-national study, looking at elections taking place between 1988 and 1994 in 38 countries, Wilkin, Haller, and Norpoth (1997) found strong support for the retrospective voting argument. These authors argue that, despite the wide variation in political contexts across the nations included in their study, “voters around the world prove capable of practicing a standard form of economic voting. They do so by holding the major incumbent party accountable for recent economic performance” (301). The return of former communist parties in several post-communist regimes has been a phenomenon that scholars have tried to explain with the economic voting theory. A number of studies have found support for the argument that citizens’ evaluations of their nation’s economic situation play an important causal role on the electoral fortunes of incumbent governments (e.g., Duch 1993; Markowski and Toka 1998; Mishler and Rose 1996). For example, Markowski and Toka (1998) found that the electoral recoveries 26 in the early 19903 of former communist parties in Hungary and Poland can be explained by the referendum model of economic voting. According to the findings of these authors, citizens in these countries punished the sitting governments for economic downturns by returning old communist parties back to power. Other studies have found mixed support for the economic voting model. In a study looking at the 1998 presidential election in Venezuela, Weyland (2003) finds that, on the one hand, economic evaluations appear to have had a significant effect on President Hugo Chavez’s victory, but he also finds that the candidate’s personal characteristics had important effects on voters’ decision to support him. Another study that finds weak support for the economic voting hypothesis looks at Zambia, where the authors find much stronger evidence in support of non-ecOnomic factors, such ethnic group membership, traditional party affiliations, and urban/rural location (Posner and Simon 2002). A number of other works on new democracies question altogether the appropriateness of the conventional economic voting model. In a study looking at incumbent support and popular support for economic reform policies in Poland, Przeworski (1996) finds that, in contrast with the expectations of the economic voting model, higher inflation increased support for the incumbent. Similarly, looking at the 1993 parliamentary elections in Poland, Powers and Cox (1997) find that voting behavior could hardly be explained by citizens’ economic evaluations. The authors find that other issues related to social legacies of the communist regime were more salient to voters. , in a study seeking to explain the replacement of incumbent promarket, prodemocracy governments with ex-communist parties in Lithuania, Hungary, and Bulgaria, Harper 27 (2000) finds weak support for the economic voting hypothesis. Exploring the case of Mexico, Dominguez and McCann (1996) also find that retrospective and prospective assessments of the nation’s and one’s own economic conditions were only marginally related to voter intentions. They concluded that partisan, institutional, and candidate assessments provided the stronger bases for the divisions in Mexican mass public opinion. Overall, the mixed findings found in the literature of economic voting in new democratic settings suggest that voters in a transition context may not automatically respond to economic outcomes according to the conventional model, that is, by voting for the incumbent when times are good and vice versa. It appears the model must recognize that there is variability in the strength of economic voting resulting from different institutional contexts and heterogeneous populations that respond differently to economic outcomes (2001). Taking sides with this argument, I argue that the standard economic voting model cannot be applied in the same manner across developing democracies as it is in established democracies, because new democratic settings lack often the necessary contextual conditions that enable voters to act as economic voters. Furthermore, I argue that the tendency of an electorate to cast an economic vote varies also within a nation, because the levels of democratization can vary from region to region. I want here to refer to an analogy based the following statement by Norpoth (19962317) “there are signs that the inclination to [engage in economic voting] is hard-wired into the brain of citizens in democracies.” I do not debate the claim that citizens in general might be predisposed to be economic voters. However, I take issue with the claim that they are actually engaged 28 economic voters in any given democratic context. I argue that in a democracy, the “switch” has to be “turned on” in order to let citizens act as economic voters. And some democracies might not have enough “voltage” to produce economic voters. In line with this argument, I defend the claim that institutional and contextual arrangements are key determinants of economic voting. Institutions, like “flow regulators,” are in charge of distributing the “energy” (be it in the form of increased information flows, trust from citizens towards the government, or governmental responsiveness, for example) which might explain the heterogeneity of economic voting in consolidating democracies. Building on this argument, I propose that decentralization can be regarded as a potential “generator” of economic voting in new democracies. 2.5 Accountability and Decentralization in New Democracies As mentioned before, the relationship between citizens and the government is at the heart of the challenges faced by modern representative democracies. Indeed, as argued by Diamond (19992145), “creating the formal institutions of democratic local government does not guarantee that elected officials will be open and responsive or that citizens will take the opportunity to get involved. The critical link between formal institutions of local democracy and more vibrant citizen involvement is civil society.” Diamond shows that “the grth of civil society and the decentralization of political power are parallel processes, closely intertwined in the development of democracy” (19992145). One policy that has been enacted to address this problem in old and new democracies alike is the decentralization of powers from the center to the periphery. Decentralization’s broad purpose is to create an institutional context in which civil 29 society can participate more and government can respond more. In other words, one of decentralization’s indirect effects should be to facilitate accountability” from political leaders to citizens. One way for political elites, parties, and organizations to show their commitment to democracy is by fostering the deepening of democracy at the local level. “Democratic decentralization requires by definition the transfer of control to lower levels of elected government—the devolution of real authority over some aspects of the policy agenda” (Diamond 1999: 149). A popular and complex concept, which encompasses many different aspects, decentralization demands proper conceptualization. This study follows Rondinelli and Nellis’ (1986; cited in Rondinelli 1989281) definition, which states that decentralization is “the transfer of responsibility for planning, management, and the raising and allocation of resources from the central government and its agencies to field units of government agencies, subordinate units or levels of government, semi-autonomous public authorities, or non-govemmental private or voluntary organizations.” Decentralization is categorized into different dimensions,15 among the most common are: political, fiscal, and administrative (Montero and Samuels 200423). They all share the overall goal of “the dispersion of functions and power from the center to the periphery” (Rodriguez 199729). Political decentralization refers to “direct elections of state/provincial and/or local political offices” (Montero and Samuels 200425), and implies greater electoral ’4 Here I follow Schmitter’s (2004:47) definition of political accountability as a “relationship between two sets of persons or (more often) organizations in which the former agree to keep the latter informed, to offer them explanations for decisions made, and to submit to any predetermined sanctions that they may impose. The latter, meanwhile, are subject to the command of the former, must provide required information, explain obedience or disobedience to the commands thereof, and accept the consequences for things done or left undone.” '5 Decentralization is categorized by various scholars in somewhat different ways. Rodriguez (1997), for example, refers to four types of decentralization: political, spatial, administrative, and market decentralization/privatization. 30 competition at the subnational level. When political powers are decentralized, it is assumed that both citizen participation and representative government will increase (Rodriguez 199729). By having more autonomy from the center, subnational politicians should depend also directly on their constituents’ electoral support — this is one reason why electoral competition increases. However, and as Montero and Samuels (200427) warn, in practical terms, political decentralization by itself does not mean that the subnational unit is fully “decentralized.” If the state/province is politically decentralized, but lacks resources or policy autonomy, open and competititve elections become fairly meaningless. Thus, political decentralization is highly interrelated with the other two dimensions: Fiscal decentralization, which refers to the degree of autonomy subnational units have over their resources (both revenues and expenditures); and administrative (or policy) decentralization, which is defined as “the relative authority or responsibility that state/provincial and local governments have to set goals, muster resources, and administer and implement public policy” (Montero and Samuels 200427). Only the interplay between political power and resources can help overcome the common “overburdened and underresourced” problem (Diamond 19992140). Since the 19708, decentralization has been placed high on the political agendas of many nations across the world. Each nation’s individual motivations vary, but the basic argument is that decentralization increases governmental efficiency of service provisions and responsiveness at the local level (Rondinelli 1989). An overarching argument leading decentralization efforts in new democracies is that by delegating powers to lower levels of government, the central government can be prevented from preserving its authoritarian (central) grip of power. This is especially true in post-colonial Africa, post-authoritarian 3l Latin America, and post-communist Eastern Europe. These regions shared the commonality of tight central powers that eventually grew tainted by corruption, inefficiency, and unresponsiveness. To dilute this centralist tradition, decentralization of state power and democratization of government at the local level was adopted in many nations. Pressures and/or incentives to decentralize came from various sources, such as neoliberal reforms, international lending agencies, democratization processes, sociostructural causes, and political-institutional forces (Montero and Samuels 2004). A number of observers of democracy have argued that decentralization processes have been key to democratic opening and furthermore, for deepening democracy. This argument rests on the assumption that the size of a political unit is directly linked with the success of its democratic system (Diamond with Tsalik 1999:117-160). That is, the smaller a country (or political unit), the greater its likelihood to sustain its democracy. This argument makes the case for devolution of power to lower levels of government through institutional arrangements such as federalism and decentralization. According to its supporters, decentralization translates into the empowering of local-level actors, which develops grassroots democracy. Following Diamond (19992121- 122), local democracy sustains democracy in five major ways. First, decentralization enhances citizen’s educated involvement in the democratic process. A strong local government facilitates citizens’ participation in the decision-making and policymaking processes. Citizens learn hereby firsthand about the workings of the government and are increasingly aware of the value of democracy for the community as a whole. This argument is strongly supported in Putnam’s study of Italy (1993), in which a strong “civic community” is found to be determinant in sustaining democracy. Second, 32 decentralization is thought to increase accountability and responsiveness from the government to the citizens. This argument follows the idea that the more informed and engaged citizens are in the governmental process, the more likely they are to ask their political leaders to address their needs. Overall, it has been found that citizens feel closer to lower levels of government and therefore more confident and satisfied in their capacity to influence local government in contrast with a distant national government (Diamond 1999:125-126). Third, local leaders are supposed to be more representative of the community than national politicians. Fourth, the dynamics of a local government facilitate the practice of checks and balances vis-a-vis the center. The idea is that it would be far more difficult for the central government to abuse its power, if local governments — via citizens— develop local oversight systems. Fifth and lastly, decentralization of political power means that opposition parties have a real chance of winning office. Since parties in power have a real probability of being defeated, opposition parties are more likely to accept defeat. This clearly enhances governmental legitimacy both from the parties’ and voters’ perspectives. According to this view, decentralized governments are expected to increase both the institutional clarity in the political context and citizens’ overall trust in the system. However, a number of empirical studies exploring this link have found inconclusive or mixed results. While some scholars (Putnam 1993; Seong 2000) have found evidence supporting the positive relationship between decentralized local governments and citizens’ satisfaction with the system, other researchers have questioned whether decentralization actually results in “good” local government. As explained by Diamond (1 99921 32-138), decentralization presents some potential problems. First, it can lead to 33 the preservation or creation of “authoritarian enclaves.” Recent studies on subnational politics have demonstrated that decentralization can empower “bad” local governments as much as “good” local governments (Cornelius 1999; Fox 1994). For example, subnational populist leaders can mismanage decentralized resources in order to retain or extend their oligarchical grip of power, which leads to corruption and political patronage (Prud’homme 1995; Diamond 1999; Stepan 2000). Second, “small size may also create strong pressures for conformity and intolerance of difference” (Diamond 19992134). Third, revenue decentralization can create greater disparities across regions. For instance, rural areas are put at a disadvantage vis-a-vis urban centers, because they do not have as many resources to generate revenues by themselves. Looking at the effects of redistributive policies within fiscal decentralization, Prud’homme (1995) has argued that far from reaching equity across regions, decentralization policies are likely to exacerbate disparities, if they are not accompanied with proper administrative checks and balances. Similarly, other studies warn against the transfer of policy authority without adequate financial support (e.g., Bahl and Linn 1994). Fourth, decentralization can lead to “waste, redundancy, and confusion” (Diamond 19992136). For instance, services might be duplicated if the lines of responsibility are blurred. Also, if subnational actors are given extreme autonomy without major responsibility, the danger of gridlock is always there. Diamond (19992137) refers to Brazil as an example of this trap, arguing that “it seems beyond question that the level of political decentralization in Brazil constitutes a major obstacle to democratic consolidation.” This review suggests that the effectiveness of decentralization policies is contingent upon different factors that vary across and within nations. These factors could 34 be “packaged” into the following two points. a) Governments (both incumbents and opposition) need to depend on constituents’ electoral support for their survival, that is, decentralization policies have a strategic power; and b) decentralization policies have to be accompanied with adequate funding and enforcement mechanisms. 2.6 Conclusion Drawing upon the empirical and theoretical debates reviewed above, I explore in this dissertation hypotheses about economic voting at the subnational level of government in Mexico. The broader purpose of this analysis is to explore the relevance of decentralization measures in a new democracy on subnational electoral behavior. The normative purpose is to find out whether and to what extent electoral accountability is working within a new democracy. Extending the theory of economic voting to the Mexican context presents interesting theoretical challenges. On the one hand, given Mexico’s political and economic contexts, the presence of economic voting appears questionable. To begin with, the centralized nature of the 71-year PRI regime did not foster the development of a responsive relationship between the government and citizens. Further, the strong presidential system leaves the extent to which voters can distinguish between presidential, congressional, and moreover, subnational policy realms open to debate. The low level of institutionalization of the party system (Mainwaring 1999) and the clientelistic nature of politics (Fox 1994) suggest also important limitations to governmental accountability. Finally, the study of economic voting in the Mexican context is a challenging one, because there is no reelection of any kind. Reelection is 35 generally assumed to be a key element for accountability to work (Manin, Przeworski, and Stokes 1999248). Despite these theoretical challenges, this dissertation aims to shed light on this understudied but critical question of democratic accountability. Thus, the central argument of this study is that Mexican citizens behave as economic voters, but that their propensity to do varies with the degree of decentralization of the state they live in. Thus, voters in more decentralized states will be more likely to be economic voters. This happens, I argue, because more decentralized states will have the needed contextual conditions (institutions) that allow voters to use elections as an accountability mechanism (vertical accountability), and make politicians responsive. State-level politicians, in turn, will be more likely to develop greater autonomy from the central government and take their constituents into account, because political leaders derive their power primarily from subnational electoral support. Following Garman, Haggard, and Willis (2001), I argue that the success of decentralization depends largely on the political incentives of national-, state- and local-level authorities. Only if they derive their political power from local constituencies and they have the needed financial viability to fulfill their responsibilities, then decentralization is likely to function, increasing the levels of clarity of responsibility and, eventually, producing accountability. 36 Chapter 3. The Mexican Case 3.1 Introduction This chapter provides the contextual framework for analyzing the Mexican case. It concentrates on the transformation of the contemporary Mexican political system. In doing so, I review the political trends that took place in Mexico’s recent history. Specifically, I discuss the highly centralized one-party regime established by the PRI, in which mechanisms of accountability were seriously curtailed. I also highlight the gradual development of a series of reforms that led to the slow political liberalization of the Mexican political system. Among the major political changes that the various sets of reforms unleashed, I focus on the decentralization of political and economic powers, which so dramatically reshaped the world of subnational elections, as well as relations between the center and the periphery. The chapter is divided into three parts. The next section draws upon history to describe the institutionalization processes that defined Mexico’s (un)democratic evolution and present “difficult democracy.”l6 This allows exploring the nature of the post-revolutionary regime, in particular the institutionalization process that worked so well to achieve and maintain political stability, as well as steady economic development at least until the 19705, but also to hinder the development of a competitive party system. This section looks at the resulting intergovernmental relations within Mexico’s powerful presidential system, in which the figure of the president grew legitimate but not accountable to the citizens (Levy and Bruhn 20012132). The third section reviews ’6 A term coined by Vargas Llosa (2000), after Mexico formally transited to democracy in 2000. Earlier, Vargas Llosa had referred to the Mexican system as the “perfect dictatorship.” 37 Mexico’s political liberalization process, which led to the gradual empowerment of the opposition and, eventually, to the culmination of the democratic transition in 2000. I emphasize the high levels of variation in terms of democratic development that exist across the Mexican states. Finally, I review the literature looking at the Mexican voter, setting the stage for the empirical analyses in chapters 4 and 5. 3.2 The Hegemonic Party System Until recently, Mexico’s political system was best known for its “longest one- party rule.” The PR] achieved during its 71-year rule to establish itself in such a powerful position that, for most Mexicans, the party was equivalent to the Mexican state. In this section, two institutional legacies are discussed: the PRI’s one-party rule, and the centralized inter-governmental system. Without a doubt, the Mexican Revolution (1910-1917) had lasting consequences that shaped post-revolutionary politics in Mexico. Violence did not end with the end of the revolution.17 In 1917, the country was in need of some kind of peaceful mechanism to create political order and bring unity. To fill in this vacuum, a political party was fonned—a party that would encompass all power factions into a strong central authority, which would in turn control the distribution of power among selected powerholders. As Mexican political historian Lorenzo Meyer so clearly stated, since its formation, the goal of the party was not electoral politics but to “administer power without sharing it” (1986231). ’7 See Meyer and Aguilar Camin (1986) for a detailed account of the immediate post-revolutionary period. 38 Following the founding 1929 of the Institutional Revolutionary Party (Partido Revolucionario lnstitucional, PR1),18 the government reached out to incorporate different interest groups into its structure.19 Institutionalization was the regime’s principal tool to centralize power, and a huge strategic success, as Levy and Bruhn argue: “...the genius of institutionalization lay in how the regime attained such extensive control without more blatant and brutal repression” (2001259). Among the most important groups incorporated formally and informally in Mexico’s interest group structure were the military, the Catholic Church, business, peasantry, organized labor, intellectuals, and the media. Indeed, “By incorporating the organs of mobilization, the PNR controlled participation” (Klesner 1988). Corporatism, defined as “a formal relationship between selected groups or institutions and the government or state” (Camp 2003212), was the PRI’s device to channel the most influential groups’ demands (the labor, agrarian, and popular sectors), enabling the government to control public demands. Thus, through a series of contract- like relationships, in which the regime provided resources and/or support to advance political careers in exchange for electoral support. The PRI managed to develop an almost incontestable control. This dynamic had serious consequences for the further development of institutions that were' designed to guarantee competitive and democratic participation, but in practice were seriously weakened. Hence, the resulting regime was a stable one, because it maintained a tight base of support from a wide array of interest groups, but it was, I argue, also a regime that did not produce a culture of accountability in its citizens. '8 The PR] had two antecedents: in 1929, the party was named National Revolutionary Party (Partido Nacional Revolucionario, PNR), then it was shortly renamed the Party of the Mexican Revolution (Partido de la Revolucion Mexicana, PRM). It finally acquired its current name in 1946. For a study looking at the origins and transformation of the party, see Garrido (1989). '9 For a detailed discussion on the role of groups in the Mexican political system, see Camp (19962125- 1 SO). 39 Accountability took only place in counted sets of relationships; among them perhaps the most important occurred between the president,20 who personified the PRI’s power, and the “revolutionary family” or leadership elite, which stemmed directly from the FRI-structure.21 This system was based for the most part on bargaining relations that sustained the PRI’s ruling elite across the nation. In contrast with other nations, there was little overt repression; control was primarily exercised by either accepted political bargain or cooption. Therefore, even though in formal terms a system of checks and balances existed in Mexico, in practice it was overridden by an overpowering presidency, which was based on a tight unified government, high party discipline, and by having the president as the head of the party (Weldon 1997). Thus, political accountability existed only to regulate these often corrupted power relationships that excluded almost entirely citizens’ political participation. The processes of political recruitment and nomination became crucial in the formation and maintenance of this political elite (Camp 1980, 1996). At the very top of the pyramid, the president recruited candidates based on loyalty ties, and distributed them among the most prestigious positions within the PR1 and the government in general. This rewarding system extended to the other levels of government; upper level politicians such as governors in turn secured political loyalty by recruiting lower level functionaries. 772115, a successful political career depended upon establishing a patron-client relationship with a successful political superior, because “hegemony meant that political ambition and 2° Mexico’s stron g presidentialism has been extensively studied. See, for example, Martinez Asssad (1992) and Weldon (1 997). 2’ The “revolutionary family” comprised former presidents, powerful regional and national leaders, as well as leaders of Mexico’s major interest groups. These interest groups cross-cut the entire political spectrum from lefi to right, but still fit within the ideologically flexible “catch all” revolutionary family. The structure of this group was maintained through loyal ties to the president, fear of political defeat, and self- interest to retain power, prestige, and wealth. The resulting consensus, headed by the president, drove Mexico’s political and economic development. 40 the attainment of office were not viable outside the party” (Diaz -Cayeros 1997). In fact, this dynamic resulted in a hierarchical network of political cliques22 through which politicians negotiated positions and guaranteed PRI’s hegemony at all levels of government. This clientelist23 system extended from the president all the way to the lower ranks of local government, and excluded the voter from any decision-making process. Political and Economic Centralization It has been frequently observed that Mexico “has a particularly centralist system of government, even by Latin American standards” (Nickson 19952200). During the PRI- regime, relations between the different levels of government were determined by the highly centralized nature of Mexico’s political system. Even research on subnational politics was largely understudied, and it was not until the 19905 that the explorarion of subnational politics took life (e.g., Cornelius 1999; Lujambio 2000; Rodriguez 1997; Rodriguez and Ward 1995). Politically, governors and other state-level officials represented extensions of the president’s power. Just as described before, governors owed their political loyalty to the president, who directly appointed them. Therefore, the tacit agreement was that governors would keep social and political calm in their states. They achieved this by appointing or nominating other state-level officials, such as municipal presidents, making sure hereby that their own collaborators would in turn govern in line with the PRI. However, if a governor was not capable of regaining electoral support for the PR1 for some reason, then 22 In Mexico, these teams or groups are known as camarillas, defined as “a sort of nested series of hierarchical groups under the aegis of a national or regional political leader” (Ward 19952138). 23 Clientelism is defined here as “a relationship based on political subordination in exchange for material rewards” (Fox 1994: 1 53). 41 he was likely to be replaced. In fact, the rate at which presidents removed governors is a good indicator of the degree of intrastate conflict in Mexico (Eisenstadt 2004). Not surprisingly, these “governing” and “electoral” styles were frequently (and increasingly) a source of conflict within states and municipalities. Governors and municipal presidents chosen by the president or by the incumbent governor were often unpopular with the general public and members of the local government (Cornelius and Craig 1991226). Accountability mechanisms just could not develop within this closed system. The value of regions, elections and that of voters were seriously harmed. Mexican writer Carlos Monsivais succinctly captured this reality: “The operation that stripped the provinces of their possibilities for proportional growth and fair treatment had several angles. Politically, the Partido Revolucionario Institucional (Institutional Revolutionary Party, PRI) confiscated autonomy thanks to the wiles of corporativism, the fusion of personal economic interests and administrative rights, the brutal and systematic repression of dissidence, depoliticization (in many ways the systematic exclusion of citizens from the public sphere), and misinformation via the hijacking of interpretations and gross reduction in access to news” (19922248). Economically, post-revolutionary Mexico evolved in a parallel manner to the political intergovernmental arrangement during this period: extremely centralized. Just as the PRI-regime managed to control subnational leaders by political means, it managed as well to centralize economic power. The adoption of import substitution industrialization (ISI) was adopted as the official model of development in the early 19405, and it further concentrated resources in the federal government. The ISI served the PRI to limit, in a legitimate way, the authority of subnational leaders over financial matters, tightening hereby control of the center over the periphery. The pursuit of a “national goal” (industrialization) justified placing local interests to a second place. However, this was 42 only the official discourse. In fact, for politicians, the primary goal was to secure their own political careers. Again, the PRI secured a federal arrangement that limited local fiscal power by ensuring that local politicians could retain office, or by offering attractive careers. Along with ISI, a nationwide tax system established in 1948 served the PR1 as another tool to centralize economic power. This fiscal agreement was reached through the introduction of the national sales tax.24 Mexican politicians faced a tradeoff between keeping control over financial resources and tax authority or reducing their electoral and career risks. Eventually, local politicians decided for the latter (Diaz-Cayeros 1997). The current intergovernmental fiscal arrangement of Mexico was established in 1980, with the creation of the National System of Fiscal Coordination. States “voluntarily” joined the system, giving up several taxing powers in exchange for revenue-sharing grants from the federal government. Thus, the federal government consolidated its fiscal centralization by becoming the only level of government allowed to levy taxes a wide array of issues. States still retained theoretically the capacity to collect certain taxes, however, with time, the federal government came to monopolize all sources of revenue and states grew increasingly dependent on tax revenue shares (participaciones), which increasingly came to constitute the most important source of local government finance (Figure 3.1). In sum, the intergovernmental political arrangement developed by the PR1 was based on a tight centralization of political and economic powers. Politically, regional politicians accepted this arrangement because it was the only way to secure their political ambitions, and because they required federal financial support to maintain their own 24 For an in-depth study of Mexico’s fiscal system during the first half of the 20'” century, see Diaz-Cayeros (1 997). 43 electoral alignment. In this context, the electorate was excluded for the most part from the political realm. Economically, the states grew increasingly (and to different degrees) dependent on the federal govemment. Public revenues were used by the PRI as an ideological weapon. Clearly, this arrangement hindered states’ capacity to manage their own resources and be responsive to local constituencies, because there was no need to do SO. 3.3 Reform and Transition Since the 19705, the PRI was forced to gradually introduce a number of political and electoral reforms. At first, these reforms were driven by the PRI’s political interest to maintain its centralized control. Unintendedly, however, it permitted opposition parties to compete effectively, which eventually favored greater autonomy for subnational governments and unleashed the democratic transition process. Political liberalization in Mexico dates from the political opening that occurred in the early 19705 in response to increasing demands for greater democracy and representation unleashed by the student movement of 1968. In an effort to both regain its credibility and sustain its legitimacy, the PRI government increasingly experimented with reallocating power by introducing proportional representation seats in the Congress; by giving more autonomy to local governments; and by recognizing selected electoral victories of opposition parties at both the state and the local levels. As Smith (1979) emphasized earlier, the question was one of “limited pluralism;” the limits needed to be extended, without sacrificing control over legitimacy. The reallocation of power in no way meant any intention to loosen central control. 44 The PRI, however, miscalculated. As a result of the opposition parties acquiring sufficient strength in the Chamber of Deputies (lower house) to have a say in the policy process, major changes followed in electoral matter (see Figure 3.2). In 1989, the Federal Electoral Institute (Instituto Federal Electoral, IF E) was created as a completely autonomous institute in order to conduct the entire electoral process in a professional manner. The establishment of the IF E is indeed a major breakthrough in the process of Mexican democratization because it finally broke the direct link between the official party and the institution that administers elections. The previous institution for monitoring elections, the Federal Electoral Commission, was run directly by the interior secretary as part of the executive branch. The Federal Electoral Tribunal (Tribunal Federal Electoral, TRIFE) was also created in 1989 as an autonomous body capable of challenging IFE decisions.25 The 1993 and 1994 electoral reforms extended the autonomy and jurisdiction of the IFE, and further decreased PRI’s overrepresentation in Congress. Measuring the Rise of the Opposition The opposition in Mexico has been traditionally divided primarily into two parties representing both sides of the political spectrum: on the right, the National Action Party (Partido Accio’n Nacional, PAN) and the Party of the Democratic Revolution (Partido de la Revolucion Democrdtica, PRD) on the left.26 Until the 19805, opposition political parties were closely controlled or outlawed altogether. In fact, until 1979 only those parties that did not threaten the PRI-regime (the so-called “satellite” parties) were permitted to take part in elections. 2’ See Eisenstadt (2004) on the development of Mexico’s electoral justice. 2" For in-depth analyses of the PAN and PRD, see Mizrahi (2003) and Bruhn (1997), respectively. 45 To measure and distinguish among the different degrees of electoral competition taking place across the Mexican states place from 1988 onwards, I applied two indexes developed within the American context: the Ranney Index and the Holbrook-Van Dunk Index. The Ranney Index is an indicator of the degree of two-party competition in the US states. This index was developed in Ranney’s (1976) Parties in State Politics originally published in 1965. The original measure is actually a measure of the strength of the Democratic Party in state government. It takes into account the proportion of seats won in the state House and Senate elections, the Democratic percentage in the gubernatorial election, and the percentage of the time the govemorship and state legislature were controlled by the Democratic Party. These factors are averaged together over a specified period of time, yielding a measure that ranges from 0 (complete Republican domination) to 1 (complete Democratic domination). The midpoint, of course, indicates evenly divided control, or “perfect competition”. I adapted the index to the case of Mexico by using three basic dimensions: a) Proportion of success: the percentage of votes won by the PRI in gubernatorial elections and the percentage of seats won by the parties in the (state/local) legislature b) Duration of success: the length of time the parties controlled the govemorship and the length of time the PRI controlled the legislature c) Frequency of divided control: the proportion of time the govemorship and the legislature has been divided The resulting index is a measure of control of government, with a score of 0 indicating complete control by the opposition and a score of 1 indicating absolute PRI control. The values of the Ranney party control index were calculated for two periods; 46 1972-1989, and 1990-2004. 1989 is taken as the limit of a one-party phase, taking the first opposition victory of a govemorship as the threshold point. The results are presented in Tables 3.1 and 3.2. Several patterns can be identified. During the first period, no state qualified in either of the last three categories: two-party, modified one-party opposition, and one-party Opposition. Only Nuevo Leon reached the modified-one party PRI category. The results reflect the political scenario of a hegemonic party system: the PRI had an indisputable advantage over the opposition. The scenario looks quite different during the second period. No state falls into the one-party PRI category, while 18 states qualify in the modified one-party PRI category and 12 in the two-party group, which can be considered the ideal. Only Baja California falls in the modified one-party opposition category. All two-party states had experienced opposition rule. The utility of the Ranney index as a measure of party competition is realized by folding the scale so the two noncompetitive extremes are brought together at the low end and the midpoint becomes the high point: 1 — (Ranney - .5). The resulting index ranges from .5 (no competition) to 1 (perfect competition). The Folded Ranney Index is presented in Table 3.3. Different authors have detected a number of limitations present in the Ranney index; a) The index is based exclusively on state offices and does not reflect the strength of the parties at other levels; b) the index gives more weight to some state offices than to others; the way the index is constructed, the state legislature is given much more weight than the govemorship; and c) this measure of interparty competition is a “snapshot of a moving object” and does not capture change. The Hobrook-Van Dunk Index was designed to address these limitations. It is based on district-level outcomes in state 47 lt’fl legislative elections. When applying the index to the Mexican case, I used municipal- elections data instead. Complete absence of competition is indicated by a score of O on the district-level measure. This would be a case where all candidates are unopposed. As the scale increases from 0, it indicates greater competition. Table 3.3 presents the values for both the Holbrook-Van Dunk index and the Folded Ranney index. The states are ordered according to their value on the municipal-level measure. For both indicators, higher values present more competition. The Holbrook-Van Dunk index seems to measure competition much more directly than the (Folded) Ranney index. The strongest case for face validity can be made for the municipal-level indicator. My reasoning is as follows: the Ranney index is based largely on aggregate party strength in government, not on actual election results. The only component of the Ranney index that takes into account any individual election results is the gubernatorial election component. Given that only one gubernatorial election is held every six years, it is possible that the results of this election may not represent the true degree of competition in the state. In short, the Ranney index is really a measure of party control of state government, not the competitiveness of state elections. On the other hand, the Holbrook-Van Dunk index is based entirely on actual outcomes in state legislative municipalities. Another difference is that the Ranney index is specifically oriented to two-party competition, whereas the municipal-level measure is based on overall electoral competition, regardless of the number of parties. There is some overlap between the two indices, suggesting that southern states tend to be the least competitive and northern and center states tend to be the most 48 competitive. Also, both indexes (Figures 3.4 and 3.5) illustrate the enormous changes in proportions of competition across time. Both indexes coincide on the two states with the least degree of competition in the recent period: Hidalgo and Quintana Roo. According to the Folded Ranney Index, Baja California, Baja California Sur, Chihuahua, Guanajuato, and Michoacan have the most degrees of competition between 1990 and 2002, while in the Holbrook-Van Dunk index the states of Aguascalientes, Jalisco, Nuevo Leon, Querétaro, and Zacatecas appear also among the most competitive ones. The indexes certainly exhibit the great increase in competition from one period to the next. And they also show the prevailing unevenness of competition across states. Campeche, Hidalgo, Nayarit, Oaxaca, and Quintana R00 are still remarkably behind. Altemation and Divided Government Mexico’s unicameral state legislatures were profoundly transformed during this time as well. Just as was the case in the federal Congress, electoral reforms opened the doors of local congresses to the opposition with the installment of proportional representation (PR) seats (Figure 3.6). Shifting steadily towards pluralism, Figure 3.7 illustrates the dramatic transformations taking place in local-level politics: from complete control of seats in local congresses until 1974, the PRI counted with just below 50 percent of total of seats by 2004. Figures 3.8 and 3.9 show similar trends through different indicators of the growing presence of the opposition at the local level of government. For instance, Figure 3.8 illustrates how one party (the PRI) had a majority 127 contro in all 32 local legislatures prior to 1988, excluding third parties from the 27 Majority here means at least two-thirds of total seats. 49 decision-making process. By 1993, the PRI had control over 23 local legislatures, and by 1999 only over two. The new significance of local legislatures in Mexico has been extensively explored by Ward (1995), Ward and Rodriguez (1999), and Lujambio (2000) who argue that non-PRI governments at the local level have indeed presented different styles of governing. For instance, when looking at early PAN governments in Chihuahua and Ciudad Juarez, Ward (19952141) finds that “the panista administrations of 1983-96 were characterized by operations that resembled business as much as public bureaucracies. They sought to emphasize fiscal responsibility and avoided debt financing of public works. . .There was greater transparency in municipal financing; budgets and expenditures were posted and published regularly (an innovation that the PRI subsequently maintained.” In a different study that looks at the six Mexican states of Aguascalientes, Baja California, Chihuahua, Guanajuato, Puebla, and Oaxaca, Ward and Rodriguez (1999) find evidence that local congresses are indeed exercising greater checks and balances vis-a-vis the executive branch. In general terms, they find that contexts with greater pluralism, electoral competition, and alternation of power tend to produce more responsive non-PRI state executives to local legislatures. Within this context, both government performance and voters began to matter. Along this line, divided government became a novelty in Mexico. The first divided government took place in Baja California in 1989. Between 1989 and 1994, six more states experienced divided government, while between 1994 and 2000, fifteen more cases were added to the list. At least in their early stages, divided governments have served as an important arena of oversight at the local level, as parties have to explain, for 50 de 3131 ide. obs. of d 193 example, their decision-making on legislative matters to their constituents (Ward and Rodriguez 1999; Lujambio 2000). It became clear that checks were beginning to be institutionalized through the local congress (Ward and Rodriguez 19992700). 3.4 The Mexican Voter So far, I have emphasized the effects of the PRI-regime on the institutions, and have shown that accountability mechanisms started only to work when elections were no longer only a ritual. That is, when politician’s “political survival” and ambition (Ames 1987) did no longer depend on one party, but on citizens’ electoral preferences. A crucial question to address is, within this authoritarian context, what kind of electorate developed? By reviewing the major trends of the literature on the Mexican voter, my intention is to show that the Mexican electorate was highly constrained by the authoritarian structures, and only slowly reached a level of politization that allowed voters to effectively fight for their political preferences. In this section, I organize the literature on Mexican voting behavior by making use the classification applied to the US literature on electoral behavior by Dennis (1991). The initial phase of electoral behavior studies in Mexico corresponds to a descriptive approach. The basic question is “how did an individual vote?” and it hardly approaches the question of “why?” Gonzalez Casanova (1965) is among the first authors identified within the descriptive approach. In his work, Gonzalez Casanova made some observations about the PRI’s electoral dominance. Following him, a significant number of descriptive studies were developed, dealing with specific federal (e.g., Gonzalez Graf 1988; Martinez Assad 1992); state-level elections (e.g., Molinar 1986; Aziz Nassif 1994, 51 2000); and broader analyses of electoral geography (e.g., G6mez-Tagle 1989, 1992). Gomez-Tagle has been considered the most representative author of this approach with her work La dificultad de perder (1989), in which she follows the decline of the PRI’s hegemony from 1961 to 1988. Her work does not include explicit models of electoral behavior, but her analysis makes the assumption that the interaction between big actors, such as the state and social groups explain this behavior. More recently, descriptive studies have been advanced by more refined measurement and description instruments, such as indexes of competition (e.g., Pacheco 1986). The use of public opinion polls has also developed the state of this line of research by providing individual-level data. Political magazines, such as Este Pais (since 1991), Nexos (since 1989), Etcétera (since 1993), V02 y Voto (since 1993), and the newspaper group Reforma-E1 Norte (since 1994) have made extensive and intensive use of public opinion polls, producing both basic reports in newspapers and magazines of a large number of polls at the national and state levels, as well as launching important public opinion-based scholarly work (e. g., Dominguez and Lawson 2004; Moreno 2003). The sociological approach has dominated voting behavior studies in Mexico. The most important variable used by a majority of these studies to explain the electoral bases of political parties has been the urban-rural divide (Pacheco 1986). Other authors (Molinar and Weldon 1990; Klesner 1995) considered other socioeconomic variables (such as marginalization or literacy rates) and regional variables to describe electoral behavior. One of the most representative works within this tradition is Zavala’s (1991) analysis of the 1988 presidential election. He finds that variables, such as the number of miles of major highways, the ratio of individuals in the lower economic strata, and the 52 ratio of Catholics and professionals within the population, were some of the explaining factors of the PRI vote in 1988. He asserts that the PRI in 1988 owes its victory to the rural population, to self-employed workers, labor unions, the unemployed, and the illiterate (1991). In Mexico, the development of the psychological approach followed to some extent the Michigan School, but introduced a very important modification: the concept of party identification was substituted by the one of political culture as axis of the explaining causal models of electoral behavior. This was due to the hegemony of a single party and the non-competitive character of the elections, which basically took away any meaning to the party identification concept. In its place, the psychological approach in Mexico sought to explain voting behavior, especially the electoral choice of Mexican voters based on a complex group of affective and psychological attitudes and predispositions encompassed in the concept of political culture. The first research work making use of the political culture concept is the landmark study The Civic Culture (Almond and Verba 1963). In regards to the Mexican case, the authors found that only a minority of citizens possessed a participant culture, while the great majority exhibits a parochial or subject political culture. They explain this political culture pattern as being consistent with the authoritarian tendencies that they observed in the political institutions at that time. That is, according to the authors, the Mexican authoritarianism was based on strong socio-psychological basis: the predominance of individuals with a parochial or subject political culture. Without doubt, The Civic Culture is one of the most influential works in studies on Mexican politics. In fact, during the following decade, over a dozen of other works 53 used the database that Almond and Verba gathered For example, Segovia (1975), in his work La Politizacion del Nina Mexicano, found also evidence supporting the theory that political culture was indeed responsible for the political structure of the country because, within an authoritarian regime, political socialization is inevitably strongly influenced by the state. Other scholars developed the psychological approach further by leaving aside the concept of political culture and including party identification. For instance, Moreno (1993) applies directly the Michigan Model to the Mexican case. By retaking the concept of party identification, he finds that in the 1991 mid-tenn election the most important variable of the voter’s choice was the voter’s previous partisan sympathy. Within the rational approach, an early study of this kind was undertaken by Ames (1970). Based on the assumption that governmental policies affect people’s electoral choices in an unequal manner, depending on the magnitude of the individual’s needs, Ames sought to explain electoral participation and vote direction from 1952 to 1967 by using aggregated state-level data. By measuring both direct (number of rank and file in each state and the benefits that the government provided) and indirect factors (such as urbanization, proximity to the US border, and the structure of the opposition), Ames intended to find a correlation between public investment and PRI electoral victories. However, he found that the indirect factors have a greater explanation power than the direct ones. Among the many studies looking at the electoral impacts of provision of public goods, Molinar and Weldon (1994) analyze the impact of the controversial social development program Solidarity (Programa Nacional de la Solidaridad, PRONASOL). 54 The authors looked at the electoral impact of this program and clearly found that electoral and political conditions had a stronger say than poverty per se in the selection criteria. They found that public investment was greater in those states in which the PRI got a clear majority of votes in the 1988 federal elections. In these states, this study shows a clear rational relationship between voters and the PRI. The outcomes were different in states with higher opposition presence: in states where Cardenas with the CD (Corriente Democra'tica) 1988 and the PRD 1991 were stronger, public investment was higher than in states where the PAN was stronger. Molinar and Weldon conclude that these differences are due to the different electoral bases of the opposition; while the PRD’s base was similar to the PRI’s, the PAN’s basis was substantially different. It made therefore more sense for the PRI-govemment to invest more in those PRD-strong states. Baennan (1994) makes use as well of economic arguments to explain the left vote in presidential elections between 1946 and 1988. His model uses aggregated data, including balance trade, inflation rates, and income per capita. His hypothesis states that as economic conditions worsen, Mexican voters vote left to punish the PRI, hoping that the left would improve the economic situation. His results show that Mexican voters respond indeed to such macroeconomic indicators by punishing or rewarding the PRI. Among the first works using individual-level data, Kaufman (1971) and Coleman (1975) are important to mention. Kaufman (1971) looked at the level of material satisfaction and its relationship with political participation and support of political institutions. He found a positive relationship between both material and political satisfaction. On the other hand, Coleman (1975) found that PAN support is not 55 determined by a certain social class or religious group, but by voters who vote against the PRI by voting for the PAN — a strategic vote. More recently, Dominguez and McCann (1996) represented for a long time the most important work of the rational approach. By analyzing two pre-electoral polls of 1988 and 1991 they introduced a two-step (or anti-PRI) model, which provided a rational explanation of vote choice. According to the model, voters first asked themselves whether or not they want to support the PRI. Second, if a voter decided not to support the PRI, s/he would either abstain or vote for the opposition, regardless of whether the opposing party with the highest probability of defeating the PRI coincided with the voter’s ideological preferences. Thus, for a majority of voters, elections were nothing more than a symbolic plebiscite or a strategic move. Buendia (1995) questions Dominguez and McCann (1995) model by stressing the importance of retrospective and prospective economic factors, presidential image, and risk aversion to explain the 1994 presidential vote. His evidence comes from a nationwide poll. Buendia finds that Mexican retrospective voting existed, but that it was mainly a sociotropic vote and not a sociotropic one. He also finds strong evidence about the effect of risk aversion hurting both opposition parties. Moreno and Yanner (1995) present a comprehensive model of the 1994 election based on a preelectoral nationwide poll and an exit poll. They find consistent evidence that partisan identification was a strong predictor of the vote. Contradicting Dominguez and McCann’s (1995) and Buendia’s (1995) claims, they see structural factors still closely related to the direction of the vote. Their evidence regarding retrospective and, in general, rational voting is not consistent across the two data sets. In the exit poll they find 56 strong evidence of retrospective and issue voting, but in the preelectoral poll they only find some importance of specifically political issues. Scholars have often tried to answer the following puzzling question: “Why was it so natural for Mexican people to complain about their government officials and then vote for them, even when democratic and institutional opportunities for a real change exist?” (Cinta 19992174). For instance, Cinta (1999) and Magaloni (1994) look at this “fear of change” and test the role of uncertainty in Mexico’s electoral arena. They find that, for a long time, Mexican voters tended to be risk-averse. Effectively, the PRI was the party that received the worst evaluations at the national level, and nevertheless, it represented the option that received the highest number of votes. The PRI benefited from the record of its past performance, a record that while not fully satisfactory to everybody, at least guaranteed certainty about the govemment’s future performance. In general, researchers of Mexican electoral behavior have agreed on three basic assumptions. First, the dominant cleavage in Mexican politics has revolved around the country’s political opposition against a crumbling authoritarian regime and its electoral arm, the PRI (Dominguez and McCann 1995; Moreno 2003). The pro-govemment side includes the principal beneficiaries of clientelism and one-party rule in Mexico: government employees, owners of large businesses, members of the PRI’s state- corporatist organizations, and peasants in villages traditionally favored by the government. On the opposition side lie the professionals, small- and medium-sized businessmen, independent unions and peasant organizations, and other groups that have traditionally been abused by Mexico’s authoritarian system. In general, opposition voters 57 tend to be better educated, more engaged in politics, more urban, and younger (Moreno 2003). Second, analysts have noted a pronounced and persistent regional cleavage that divides the country roughly in half (Klesner 1995). In the North, West, and the state of Yucatan—areas where the Catholic Church remains influential and local business elites have long opposed centralized control from Mexico City—the country’s conservative PAN constitutes the main opposition force. In the poorer, more rural South, the leftist Party of the Democratic Revolution remains the principal challenge to PRI rule. Mexico thus comprises a pair of essentially two-party systems—PRD-PRI in the South, PAN-PRI in the North. Only in the capital and a handful of provincial areas does competition regularly take on a multiparty character. Third, scholars generally agree on the existence of a “floating” or strategic opposition vote among either the PAN or the PRD (Dominguez and McCann 1996). In the presidential elections of 1988 and 1994, for instance, the total opposition vote remained roughly the same, at least according to official figures. But the distribution of that vote among opposition parties varied dramatically. In 1988, the opposition sided primarily with leftist candidate Cardenas, whereas in 1994 it sided with Diego Fernandez de Cevallos of the PAN. This finding mirrors electoral swings in certain states, such as San Luis Potosi and Baja California, where the anti-PRI voters appeared to strategically switch between different opposition parties (Rodriguez and Ward 1995). The existence of this floating opposition vote tends to reinforce Mexico’s regional divide, and it suggests an element of rationality among Mexican voters. 58 .GmE “858 _1 ll.ll ill l l l lllllllllllll llllllllllllllllllllll 11' iii 1 llllll z, 903:9.» .maoumu. 1:1 mozcgwm :30 II n, filllltlltllll ll.ll 53> e e z 1 z z z z 1 z z z z 1 z z z 0 0 0 0 0 no 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Am % do do A0 ac % a. a. a. a. as o« a. e. e. 0/. .. . 898m» 000600. F” . . _ 8908.; 1')le dXW W m o8_ooo.~» 8068.3 llllillll ill l l lyllll llll lll .lll.l l l l l l ll.l.llllrll ill. l. «mafia ESE: 83.3.: £555: has. E can: i m z u L m I I -... _. 59 Figure 3.2 Number of Seats in the Chamber of Deputies, 1961-2003 500 400 2 ,_f pr, 1 ,, L-0-Total seats 300 g l g l—i—Relative Majority a) - t 200 {qr-Proportional Representation 100 T “'T' T T T 0 N b '9 Sources: IFE and www.diputados.gob.mx Figure 3.3 Party Affiliation of Governors in the 32 States, 1980-2004 301 1 25! 2o 15 ‘ +Opposition t .__— .___.___._—.. 10 ,. 0 ~ , —-v—r I —>7 fru—‘v—‘r 9 N '5 <9 '\ 9 N ‘b Source: CIDAC www.cidacorgmx 60 Table 3.1 Ranney Index” in Mexican States, 1972-1989 One-Party PRI Modified One-Party PRI Campeche Puebla Nuevo Leon 0.9737 0.9079 0.8482 Tabasco Tlaxcala 0.9668 0.9054 Hidalgo Baja California Sur 0.9626 0.9052 Guerrero Estado de Mexico 0.9595 0.9046 Zacatecas Yucatan 0.9564 0.9007 Querétaro Tamaulipas 0.9551 0.8986 San Luis Potosi Sinaloa 0.9434 0.8973 M ichoacan Chihuahua 0.9354 0.8936 Chiapas Baja California Sur 0.9343 0.8918 Morelos Durango 0.9321 0.8898 Quintana Roo Nayarit 0.9317 0.8883 Veracruz Sonora 0.9283 0.8757 Colima Aguascalientes 0.9266 0.8707 Coahuila Jalisco 0.9189 0.8545 Oaxaca Guanajuato 0.9103 0.8539 2’ The index is composed of 3 elements: a) the average percentage of the popular vote won by PR] gubernatorial candidates; b) the average percentage of the seats in the local congresses held by the PRI; and c) the percentage of all terms for governor and local congress in which the PRI had control. For each state, all 3 percentages were averaged together and carried to four decimal places. The index has a possible range of 0 (total opposition success) to 1 (total PRI success), with .5 representing absolutely two-party competition. The resulting clusters suggest the following categories (Ranney 60): .8500 or higher: one-party PR1 .6500 to .8499: modified one-party PRI .3500 to .6499: two-party .1500 to .3499: modified one-party opposition .0000 to .1499: one-party opposition 61 Table 3.2 Ranney Index in Mexican States, 1990-2004 Modified One-Party PRI Two-Party Modified One-Party Opposition Campeche Aguascalientes Baja California 0.7091 0.5475 0.2654 Coahuila Baja California Sur 0.7793 0.4956 Colima Chihuahua 0.7273 0.5201 Chiapas Guanajuato 0.8284 0.4488 Durango Jalisco 0.6745 0.4501 Guerrero Estado de Mexico 0.7901 0.6163 Hidalgo Michoacan 0.8151 0.5551 Nayarit Morelos 0.6695 0.6275 Oaxaca Nuevo Leén 0.7572 0.5091 Puebla Querétaro 0.7954 0.5563 Quintana Roo Tlaxcala 0.8176 0.5991 San Luis Potosi Zacatecas 0.7847 0.5555 Sinaloa 0.7143 Sonora 0.7181 Tabasco 0.7758 Tamaulipas 0.7678 Veracruz 0.7445 Yucatan 0.6424 Sources: CIDAC: http://www.cidac.org.mx/espanioLpolitica 2000.htm 62 Table 3.3 Holbrook- Van Dunk Index” and Folded Ranney Index” in Mexican States State Municipal-Level Competition Folded Ranney I 970-1 989 1990-2002 1 970-1 989 I 990-2002 Aguascalientes 24.88 55.38 0.6293 0.9525 Baja California 49.99 84.34 0.6082 0.7654 Baja California Sur 19.43 72.67 0.5948 0.9956 Campeche 4.01 45.26 0.5263 0.7091 Coahuila 21.79 55.13 0.5811 0.7207 Colima 44.23 59.18 0.5734 0.7727 Chiapas 7.98 63.54 0.5657 0.8284 Chihuahua 47.19 73 .37 0.6064 0.9799 Durango 27.24 70.56 0.6102 0.8255 Guanajuato 29.72 79.46 0.6461 0.9488 Guerrero 10.42 57.53 0.5405 0.7099 Hidalgo 3.00 37.56 0.5374 0.6849 Jalisco 33.92 72.65 0.6455 0.9501 México 18.02 59.58 0.5954 0.8837 Michoacan 12.02 83.34 0.5646 0.9449 Morelos 9.7 57.87 0.5681 0.8725 Nayarit 15.14 42.04 0.61 17 0.8305 Nuevo Leén 18.52 69.75 0.6518 0.9909 Oaxaca 10.23 46.38 0.5897 0.7428 Puebla 18.00 52.29 0.5921 0.7046 Querétaro 20.97 56.41 0.5451 0.9437 Quintana Roo 4.61 45.53 0.5683 0.6824 San Luis Potosi 22.26 61.5 0.5566 0.7153 Sinaloa 25.56 61.97 0.6027 0.7857 Sonora 29.27 69.29 0.6243 0.7821 Tabasco 8.33 58.69 0.5332 0.7242 Tamaulipas 24.07 60.89 0.6014 0.7322 Tlaxcala 14.46 58.98 0.5946 0.9009 Veracruz 13.45 59.46 0.5717 0.7555 Yucatan 15.8 70.3 0.5933 0.8576 Zacatecas 10.31 66.6 0.5436 0.9445 Source: CIDAC: http://www.cidac.org.mx/espaniol nolitica 2000.htm 29 The Holbrook-Van Dunk formula for statewide values of the district-level measure is: 100 — [(average %vote for winners + average margin of victory + %uncontested seats + %safe seats)/4]. A safe seat has a winning percentage of 55% or more. 1 used municipal council elections data. Since there are no uncontested seats in Mexico, I used only the 3 other elements of the formula, dividing by 3. As the scale increases from 0, it indicates greater degree of competition. 3° The formula for the folded scale is 1 — (Ranney - .5). The resulting index ranges from .5 (no competition) to 1 (perfect competition). 63 Table 3.4 Experience under Non-PRI Rule, Mexican States, 1985-2004 Year of Altemation, Year of Altemation, State Governor Local Legislature A68 1998 1995 BC 1989 1989 BCS 1999 1999 CAMP COAH COL CHIS 2000 CHIH 1992, 1998 1992, 1995 DGO GTO 1995 1997 GRO HGO JAL 1995 1995, 2003 MEX 2000, 2003 MICH 2001 2001 MOR 2000 2000 NAY 1999 1999, 2002 NL 1997, 2003 1997, 2003 OAX PUE QRO 1997 1997 QROO SLP 2003 2003 SIN SON 2000, 2003 TAB 2003 TAM TLAX 1998, 2004 VER YUC 2001 2001, 2004 ZAC 1998 2001 DP 1997 1997, 2000, 2003 Source: IFE 64 Figures 3.4 Folded Ranney Index, Mexican States, I970-2004 1 1 0.9 - 0.8 ~ 0.7 - 0.6 - 0.5 - 0.4 - 0.3 - 0.2 - 0.1 0 g, Y9 $0 $090300? V “Co I I .9965“ 90° 0&0 04° {9° 39’ 3*‘963‘ 90 e I 1 970-1 989 El 1990-2004 0.9 0.8 -— 0.7 -— 0.6 -— 0.5 -- 0.4 T 0.3 -- 0.2 -~ 0.1 - 0 1 r .— _l I Til—T l I I Q- C (a l I 1 970—1989 Cl 1990-2004 Source: Table 4. 65 Figure 3.5 Municipal-Level Competition (Holbrook- Van Dunk Index), Mexican States, 1 970-2004 I 1970-1989 I 1990—2004 -_-_ ‘WW ——- 2...... W —— WW' - :.-'-...~..---.. . . n: . . 1_t--- WW“ ~ -h"':uu. I~I.TT‘"‘“‘W-—Wn .xmumrv‘". ‘- . WWW —W } —l__— --___ "’ ‘wmi‘ims-* ’m'“ "9‘ A WV'MW.‘?I.VMWV J. z , 90 80 I I l I I I I m Q Q Q G 6 Q Q C l‘ \O m V M N c- e a {a o o ~2- 4 o s e <1- c 66 Source: Table 4. Figure 3.6 Number of Seats in Local Congresses, 1974-2004 1200 1000 800 i—o—TotalSeafts 7 Fan—Relative Ma'on't ' 600 t 1 Y1 ' 1 400 ‘-A-Proportional . _ Renegades): ' 200 0 , 1974 1989 1998 2001 2004 Sources: Lujambio (2000: 55); CIDAC:www.cidac.org.mx/dat(Ls[congresos Figure 3. 7 Distribution of Seats in Local Congresses mercent), 1974-2004 100 90 80 70 604 502 40. 30-. 20- 10 0 if, Opposition’ 1974 1989 1998 2001 2004 Sources: Lujambio (2000: 57); and CIDAC: www.cidac.org.mx/d_atos/congresos 67 Figure 3.8 Local Congresses where one party has a majority” of seats, 1978-2004 35 30- 25- 20- 15‘ 10- 5.. 0 I I I r T I T U I I I I I U I «egagexwahebneeesgu eeeessssssesssss W Source: Lujambio (2000); CIDAC http://www.cidac.org.mx Figure 3.9 Electoral Victories in MR Districts by Parties Other than PRI, 1974-2000 70 I Other Parties I PAN Percent 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Source: Lujambio (2000) 3 ' Two-thirds of total seats. 68 he M 1111 pr 81 Chapter 4. Aggregate-Level Analysis 4.1 Introduction As seen earlier, Mexico’s protracted democratic transition started at the subnational level, however, at very different paces across states. While some state governments have experienced a relatively significant history of democratic transition, other states have not had any alter nation experience. Scholars have referred to the dangers that such “subauthoritarian authoritarian enclaves” (Cornelius 199923; Diamond 1999) pose for the democratic quality of the nation as a whole. Without doubt, Mexican states vary in their degree of democratization (Hiskey 2005; Hiskey and Bowler 2005; Solt 2001, 2003), and some have certainly not developed fully in democratic terms yet. The present chapter explores the effects of macro-level data on support for the incumbent party in gubernatorial and local legislature elections in Mexico. The analysis is based on an aggregate-level data set collected for all 31 Mexican states and the Federal District covering the period between 1970 and 2004. The main observation period, however, is between 1985 and 2004, the period during which subnational politics in Mexico became competitive. During this period of time, as seen in chapter 3, Mexico underwent a series of economic and political reforms that put the democratic transition process into motion in a number of states, and eventually ended the PRI’s hegemonic rule at the national level. By looking at the effects of political and economic decentralization on voting behavior, the purpose of this chapter is twofold: First, it seeks to find out whether the straightforward relationship between economic performance and electoral results found 69 in the American and Western European contexts holds at the subnational level in Mexico. This goal represents the first step within the broader picture of the dissertation. The second purpose is to add a measurement (effects of decentralization) to the classic economic voting model. The overall goal is to see whether or not economic voting is taking place in the Mexican states, and measure the impact of economic and political decentralization on electoral outcomes. The results of this chapter support the leading argument of this dissertation in five principal ways. First, the classic economic voting hypothesis is supported by the results of the gubernatorial elections models. The results show that a state’s economic performance (measured by a state’s annual Gross State Product or GSP growth) has explanatory power when voters make an electoral decision. Second, financial decentralization—as measured by a state’s locally-generated revenues—has significant explanatory power on incumbent electoral support in gubernatorial elections. That is, a state’s level of financial decentralization (measured by its financial autonomy) vis-a-vis the federal government is positively related with electoral support for the incumbent. Third, decentralization of political power—measured by a state’s experience under a non- PRI administration—appears to be an important indicator of behavior at the polls. Pluralism and electoral competition—assumed to exist in contexts where the former hegemonic party is no longer dominant—appear to produce those institutional elements that lead to economic voting. In line with this argument and fourth, the results suggest that voters distinguish between their state’s political institutions and those at the national level. This is very significant because it points to some degree of functioning institutional clarity in the country. Finally, this chapter finds that when accounting for state-specific 70 factors, the results confirm a high degree of uneven electoral behavior across the Mexican states. Specifically, the results show that the assumed effects of decentralization do not reach unifome all states. This issue is further explored in chapter 5. 4. 2 Theoretical Considerations As reviewed in chapter 2, the classic economic voting argument dos not apply in the same manner to new democratic settings as it does in old democracies. For voters to be able to assign correctly responsibility to the respective government branch, a certain amount of clarity of responsibility is required (Powell and Whitten 1993), which can only grow under certain political conditions. Such conditions, as I argued in chapter 3, did not develop during the one-party rule in Mexico between 19291and the 19805. Democratic developments in the last twenty years reached the Mexican states on an uneven basis. Therefore, it is expected that some states have higher probability of meeting the conditions necessary for voters to be able to reward or punish their state government, while citizens in other states do not. In this analysis, economic voters are broadly defined as pocketbook or sociotropic voters. Both depend ultimately on how well the state is performing in the economy. Thus, if a state is performing well, its economic voters will support the incumbent party at the polls. What explains variation in electoral choice and therefore, in levels of accountability across the Mexican states? Given the broad variation across the states on a wide number of factors, the hypotheses explored in this chapter are based on the following three assumptions. 71 a) Regional Economic Performance Mexico is a nation rich in regional contrasts, and variations in economic development across its regions explains to a great extent this heterogeneity. States differ greatly according to a large number of factors, such as the ratio of its population working in the agricultural sector, ethnic composition, and overall marginalization levels. Higher rates of economic growth have been found to be correlated with higher levels of electoral competition, and therefore, with more effective government. b) Regional Autonomy vis-a-vis the Center As seen in chapter 3, Mexico’s states grew increasingly dependent on Mexico City for resources and political instructions. As noted in a study exploring the nature of regions in Mexico, and particularly the capacity of the central government to exercise power at the local level: “The more dependent a locality becomes on outside inputs and a more sophisticated economic infrastructure, the more dependent it is likely to become on external political centers in order to get things done, such as roads built or irrigation installed.” (Roberts 19922236). Economically, state governments control in average less than a quarter of the revenues of the federation, in contrast to the three-quarters controlled by the national government. However, states greatly differ in their levels of financial autonomy vis-a-vis the federal government. For instance, Tables 4.1 a and d present the states that, according to these indicators, are the most autonomous vis-a-vis the federal government: the Federal District, Nuevo Leon, Chihuahua, Baja California, and Jalisco. Conversely, Tables 4.1 b and c contain the states that depend the most from federal revenues, and those that produce the least amount of own revenues from taxes. Among the states that 72 appear to be the least financially autonomous are Chiapas, Guerrero, Nayarit, Oaxaca, and Tabasco. Recent studies on local politics have shown that opposition parties in power have tended to demand more autonomy from the center. For example, in a study evaluating Chihuahua’s first government of alternation (1992-1998), Aziz Nassif (2000) finds that the PAN sought to distinguish itself from the PRI by an overall reorganization of financial matters, trying to bring about transparency and increasing the state’s own revenues.32 It can be argued that the motivation behind this is that an opposition government in Mexico, once it finally wins the needed electoral support to gain office, it wants to retain that support at home and for this, money is needed. Therefore, opposition governments have tended to be more efficient in their public spending (Ward 1995). Some scholars have found that democratization. leads to decentralization processes. For instance, Beer (2004) finds that “as electoral competition has taken root at the state and municipal level in many areas across Mexico, democratically elected mayors and governors have begun to demand more autonomy from the central government and more control over local fiscal policy.” According to this view, it is expected that increased subnational competition generates pressures for fuller political and fiscal decentralization. However, just as political power underwent a gradual (and uneven) process of liberalization, decentralization, with the aim to “centralize through decentralization” under the PRI (Rodriguez 1997), took also an uneven and slow shape across the states. ’2 In fact, the panista administration (1992-1998) in Chihuahua managed to duplicate its own revenues (Aziz 2000255). However, it has been argued that the government was blamed for raising taxes, and that this contributed to the PRI’s recovery of the govemorship in 1998. 73 c) Local Political Environment Mexican states greatly differ in their political environment, which is determined by various factors. First, as I showed in chapter 3, states differ in their levels of electoral competition. States where the opposition is the weakest or almost non-existent, have been found to be fertile ground for impunity and continuing authoritarian control under the PRI (Cornelius 1999211). In fact, some states achieved truly competitive elections33 by the mid-19905, while others have not done so yet. Second, and related to this last point, a state’s political environment differs from another, if it has experienced alternation of power. The alternation of political parties in office is considered to be crucial for the process of democratization. In a strict sense, those that have not experienced alternation are still considered authoritarian regimes (Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub, and Limongi 2000). As I have argued before, if a state experiences alternation of power, the government system gains in legitimacy both within parties and citizens. As Diamond has argued: “Opposition victory at the subnational level also provides a good test of the party’s platform and its performance in government. A party that is out of power can easily criticize the governing party and make untenable claims about what it would achieve if it were in office. However, if the opposition holds power at the local level, voters have an opportunity to assess its performance” (Diamond 19992131). For instance, Rodriguez and Ward (1994; Guillén Lopez 1995; Espinoza Valle 1999), looking at Baja California, concluded that the alternation in the govemor’s office led to an improved separation of powers among the three branches of government, to greater municipal autonomy, and better administered elections. The third and last factor refers to divided 3’ I mean here that the incumbent faces a realistic probability of being defeated—or that alternation has taken place. 74 government. In contrast with the argument found in the literature on the US system, which frequently refers negatively to the consequences of divided government (gridlock), it has been argued that divided government in Mexican local legislatures is a positive phenomenon for state-level democratization. For example, Lujambio (2000267-72) argues that the open debates and negotiation taking place in divided governments serve indeed as educative experiences for both political parties and citizens. In sum, observers of subnational politics in Mexico, have argued that states that have competitive elections, have experienced an opposition government (and perhaps a divided government) exhibit different styles of governing that have led to the use of elections as mechanisms of accountability. 4.3 Hypotheses Hypothesis 1: GSP Growth Rate H1 proposes that states that perform better economically will show higher levels of support for the incumbent party, and vice versa. This hypothesis follows the classic theory of economic voting, which argues that if an individual citizen is satisfied with past economic performance, s/he will approve of the president, but if not, s/he will register disapproval. Extending this individual-level mechanism to the aggregate-level, it is expected that a similar relationship will take place between macroeconomic indicators and incumbent support at the polls. It is expected that citizens will form positive (negative) assessments of their government’s economic performance, if the economy is doing well (poorly), and consequently support (reject) the sitting government. 75 Hypothesis 2: Locally-Generated Revenues H2 proposes that states with greater financial autonomy vis-a-vis the central government will support more the incumbent party. This hypothesis is based on the following assumption: a state with more resources of its own—that is, financially more decentralized—develops more transparent institutions and thus, its citizens are more likely to reward the incumbent party. Greater financial autonomy generates elements that increase accountability, such as transparency, access to information, and/or political knowledge. According to this view, voters living under such conditions are more likely to support the incumbent party. Hypothesis 3: Revenues from the Federal Government H3 proposes that the more dependent a state is on resources from the federal government, the less support the incumbent party will get in state elections. Ideally, rational voters will reject the notion of their state being heavily dependent on the federal government, and support instead efforts designed to develop or increase their state’s financial autonomy, as autonomy means accountability. Thus, it is expected that incumbent parties will get less electoral support, the higher their total revenue depends on transfers from the federal government. Hypothesis 4: Experience under Non-PRI Rule H4 proposes that states with experience under a party other than the PR] rule will support less the incumbent party. The logic behind this hypothesis is that states which have experienced rule by parties other than the long-time hegemonic party, are more likely to have voters who assign substantive content to their voting decisions than those states which have not 76 experienced alternation of power. Experience under a party different than the PRI means that the state has high levels of electoral competition. As discussed earlier, this kind of context is likely to have high levels of access to information and a more critical civic society. Since voters have experienced rule under a different party, they tend to be less risk-averse, and are therefore more likely to express dissidence with the incumbent party, if they disapprove of the administration’s performance. 4.4 Data and Model The central question explored in this chapter is whether greater financial autonomy and alternation of political power at the state-level lead to economic voting. Thus, the units of analysis are elections for governor and state legislatures in Mexico’s 31 states (see appendix for a list of the states and corresponding years of elections included in the data set). A data set was created on a number of fiscal and political indicators, as well as economic performance variables for subnational elections taking place between 1970 and 2004. The data was drawn primarily from Mexico’s Federal Institute of Statistics (Instituto Nacional de Estadt'sticas, Geografia, e Informdtica, INEGI), Center of Research for Development (CIDAC), Banamex, and Mexico’s Federal Electoral Institute (Instituto Federal Electoral, IFE). Dependent Variable (Electoral Incumbent Support) In gubernatorial elections, incumbent support was measured by the percentage of votes that the incumbent party won in a given election, regardless of whether it maintained its control or not (see Figure 4.1). 34 In state legislature elections, incumbent support refers to the percentage of seats that the incumbent party got, also regardless of 3" 1n the cases where a party ran in a coalition, I considered the major party. 77 whether it retained a majority or not. Both majority and proportional representation seats were added and divided by the total number of seats. Independent Variables a) State-level Economic Performance To measure a state’s economic performance, this analysis relies on a state’s annual gross state product (GSP) growth rate. Growth in state-level GSP is expected to be significant and positive. The well-known argument followed here is that economic voters take into account the economic performance of the incumbent administration and will reward at the polls its positive performance. Unfortunately, no other state-level economic indicators were available.35 b) Financial Autonomy ’6 In this research, financial autonomy is measured by two dimensions: 37 A state’s own revenues and federal transfers. First, each state’s locally-generated revenues were calculated for every year. Own revenues refer to the locally-generated revenue composed of taxes, fees, patrimonial goods, and benefit fees, which were calculated by adding the figures of all four components and then obtaining the ratio vis-a-vis the total amount of revenues for the state. Per capita figures were used in the analysis. Second, each state’s federal revenues were calculated for every year. Federal revenues refer to the amount of 3’ No state-level data for inflation rate were available. Unemployment rates are available only according to “major urban areas” (INEGI), which makes it nonsuited for a state-level indicator. ’6 It is important to make a few notes on the methodology used to calculate most of these variables. I relied for the most part on figures published by the INEGI in different volumes of F inanzas Publicas y Municipales (1970-2004). Since this information was not available in electronic form, I created an extensive database including the figures for: taxes (impuestos),patrimonial goods (productos), fees (derechos), benefit fees (aprovechamientos) and participaciones for the 32 states over a period of 34 years. To make the figures comparable, I first converted all into a single unit (thousands of pesos), and then applied consumer price index figures to deflate the numbers. I added taxes, patrimonial goods, fees, and benefit fees in order to get the total of locally generated revenue. To obtain per capita figures, I relied on Mexico’s National Population Council’s (Consejo Nacional de Poblacio'n, CONAPO) yearly population information. Finally, 1 calculated an average of these numbers according to each state’s gubernatorial term. ’7 I followed Dial-Cayeros (2004) for the operationalization of subnational financial autonomy. 78 revenue sharing each state receives from the federal government. These intergovernmental transfers are composed of two figures: Unconditional federal revenue sharing (participaciones) and earmarked federal revenue (aportaciones), which means that state governments have little or no discretion over its spending. The share was also obtained vis-a-vis the total amount of revenues, and per capita figures were used in the analysis. 0) Local Electoral Environment To consider the effects of electoral competition and pluralism, states were classified according to two categories: Those that have ever experienced rule under a non-PRI party either in the governor’s office or a majority in the local legislature (Table 4.2). Control Variables a) Coattail Effects To account for the effects of increased turnout and party voting in lower level elections due to concurrent elections for higher office, I include two dummy variables, Concurrent 1 (in regards to the local legislature) and Concurrent 2 (in relation to presidential elections), to measure coattail effects. b) Divided Government Divided 1 is a dummy variable, taking a value of one when the incumbent governor’s administration is of a different party than the local legislature’s major party. Divided 2 refers to divided government in relation to the president’s party. 79 c) Fixed Effects I used a dummy variable for each state, taking Mexico City as the baseline. With this, I intend to capture differences in vote outcomes due to state-specific factors. (1) National-level Economic Indicators Two variables were included to control for the effects of national-level economic indicators: Annual national GDP per capita and national level annual inflation rate. To test the above hypotheses, I estimated a series of regressions using the following general model: Incumbent Support, = 130 + [31 GDP Growth + [32 Own Revenues + [33 Federal Revenues + [34 Non-PRI Experience + [35 Divided 1 + [36 Concurrent 1 + [37 Divided 2 + [33 Concurrent 2 + e 4.5 Analysis and Results I applied an OLS regression model to test the effects that financial autonomy and experience under a non-PRI administration have upon support for the incumbent party. Because of my interest in capturing the effects of both the more recent decentralizing fiscal efforts and the growth of electoral competition, I considered 1985 as a threshold year and focused on the elections taking place between that year and 2004.38 Generally, five gubernatorial elections (six-year terms) and twelve local congresses’ elections (three- year terms) were included for each state (see Appendix A). Specifically, the data set for ’8 1 applied the model using the data in three different time periods. First, 1 calculated an average per administration. A few cases in the last elections were calculated using only the data available until 2003. However, as different studies have shown, looking at the entire administration when trying to analyze voting behavior is not very accurate/reliable. 1 also examined the figures of the election year (Kramer 1971; Tufie 1978). In addition, I looked at the conditions of the previous year, as well as at the average of these two years (prior and election years). All three models, however, yielded similar results. I decided to focus on the one that looks at the year prior to the election, because it allows including observations from the following 2004 elections. 80 gubernatorial elections includes 112 observations and the local congress elections data set includes 209 cases. A case is defined as an election. Table 4.2 presents the results for the regressions exploring gubernatorial elections. It contains two models; Model 1 is an OLS estimate, while the regression in Model 2 includes a fixed effects variable that controls for unobserved state-specific correlates of incumbent support. Overall, Model 2 confirms the first model’s robustness, and provides a better fit for the model. The fixed-effects variable exposes the importance of considering the uneven impacts of the variables under study across the Mexican states. There is evidence suggesting that state-level factors related directly to decentralization are significant in explaining incumbent support. The classic economic voting argument (H1) is supported by the results of Table 4.2. A state’s economic performance appears to be an important explanatory factor in the support of the incumbent governor’s party at the polls. Specifically, a percentage point of grth in a state’s GSP translates into an increased support of 3.9 percent of the incumbent party. This result is very significant, because it suggests that state-level factors are included in the voting calculus, pointing specifically to a presence of economic voting at the subnational level in the Mexican context. H2 is supported as well. The results show that locally-generated revenues are positively and significantly correlated with support for the incumbent party. This result suggests that the incumbent party benefits electorally from higher locally-generated revenues.The second indicator of state-level financial autonomy, however, federal revenue, appears significant but in the opposite direction. The results might not be that surprising, given the traditional use that federal transfers often have. In fact, this variable 81 has been used by other scholars (Remmer and Ge’lineau 2003) as an indicator of the presence of patron-client relationships between the central government and the periphery. Patronage, pork barrel, and clientelistic activities can be measured by the amount of transfers the central government gives to provinces. As discussed in chapter 3, Mexican presidents under the PRI-regime used extensively clientelistic practices to maintain a tight electoral control across all governmental levels. This indicator was expected to reflect voter’s dissatisfaction (in the more decentralized, autonomous states) with their state being too dependent from the central government. On the other hand, citizens in heavily dependent and centralized states, regard resources from the federal government as necessary, and demand more of them for their development. But, they seem to never get enough of them, and thus, cast less support for the incumbent party at the polls. Experience under the opposition is significant and in the expected (negative) direction. This result means that states that have experienced an opposition government are significantly more likely to cast less support for the incumbent. The support of H4 suggests that indeed, the experience under the opposition creates certain conditions, which contribute to more critical voters. H4 is strongly supported, and it suggests that a state that has undergone an alternation of power may have developed a mechanism that decreases support for the incumbent at the polls. As mentioned earlier, one possibility is that voters in areas without some form of opposition experience remain risk-averse and, not knowing what the opposition might look like in power, prefer to keep their familiar political arrangement intact. In contrast, in states where electoral competition is surely higher and perceived by voters as legitimate, the incumbent party tends to get a lesser 82 share of the votes. In this context, voters appear to perceive they have the real option to reward or punish however they wish, which points to accountability. Among the political control variables, divided government between the governor and the president (Divided 2), is strongly significant with a negative coefficient. That is, when a state’s administration is divided, the governor’s incumbent party gets less votes, which confirms the prevailing explanatory power of partisan identity in Mexican politics—a concept which is assumed to be included in this variable. Divided government at the state level (Divided 1) reaches statistical significance in Model 2. In general, divided government translates frequently into conflicting interests among power factions, which constantly try to expose each other with the aim to throwing the other out of power. These dynamics often lead to gridlock. In a new democratic setting, however, divided government can be regarded as healthy to a certain degree (Lujambio 2000). This regression result suggests that divided government at the state-level affects incumbent support, just as divided government vis-a-vis the president does. It is important, because it points to the visibility of state-level institutions, which can only result from electoral competition and pluralism. The results for the analysis of the state legislature elections are presented in Table 4.3. The results do not show support for the hypotheses 1-3, and the prevailing importance of national-level factors in explaining incumbent support in state legislature’s elections is very clear. In contrast with the gubernatorial elections analysis, Divided 1 is significant in both models. A divided state administration means, according to these results, less support for the incumbent majority party in the state legislature. The importance of party identification is further supported with Divided 2, which suggests 83 that national-level factors have primordial importance in state congress’ elections. Experience under a non-PRI rule does show significance with a negative coefficient. Overall, these results need to be analyzed in further. 4.6 Conclusion Although the literature on economic voting presents some disagreements on the exact nature of the relationship between economic performance and public support for the incumbent, overall, presidents are believed to be punished or rewarded for their economic performance. This analysis has taken this hypothesis to the subnational level and has found significant evidence at this level across the Mexican states. The sources for the variation across the states cannot be discerned from this type of analysis, but based on the theoretical framework that the study is based on, it is possible to present some conclusions. As shown in the preceding analysis, state-level economic performance plays an important role in incumbent support in Mexican gubernatorial elections. Economic voting appears to be taking place in gubernatorial elections. A state’s economic performance entails, as discussed earlier, a wide array of factors that distinguish one state from another. Generally, states performing better economically and with experience under the opposition are more likely to gain electoral support for the incumbent government. A state’s capacity to generate its own revenues is also found to be positively correlated with the incumbent’s party support in gubernatorial elections. That is, those state governments that manage to increase their economic autonomy vis-a-vis the center are rewarded with more approval at the polls. This is an important finding, because a 84 state’s financial autonomy is a crucial indicator of the effectiveness of decentralizing policies. The general argument of this dissertation is supported hereby. Another important finding refers to the significance of the variable controlling for a state’s experience under a non-PRI administration. As discussed before, my goal was to capture the effects that an opposition party in power has on the institutional environment in a given country. Based on the assumption that such experience under the “opposition” brings about greater clarity of responsibility and thus, voters are likely to become economic voters, the findings in this chapter suggest that indeed the strength of the opposition within a state and its actual presence in government is strongly related with the way the state’s population votes. Clearly, there is a significant degree of heterogeneity within the group of Mexican states that cannot be fully accounted for by the other explanatory variables in the statistical model presented here. The next chapter looks with more detail into citizen’s motivations and state-specific factors. 85 Table 4.1 Diverse Indicators of Financial Autonomy in Mexican States, 2004 Table 4.1a States receiving highest amount of revenues from taxes (% of GDP), 2004 Table 4.1b States receiving lowest amount of revenues from taxes (% of GDP), 2004 Table 4. 1c States receiving highest amount of federal revenues (% of GDP), 2004 Table 4.1d States receiving lowest amount of federal revenues (% of GDP), 2004 Source: http://www.cidac.org.mx DF 61.44% TAM 32.20% COL 31.22% NL 16.06% VER l 1.12% CHIS 2.42% DGO 2.77% OAX 3.07% GRO 3.08% NAY 3.38% TAB 3.88% CAMP 3.99% CHIS 21.86% TAB 21.73% OAX 18.99% ZAC 16.99% NAY 16.53% GRO 15.90% TLAX 15.52% DF 2.53% NL 4.25% CHIH 5.34% BC 5.91% QROO 5.92% VER 6.47% COAH 6.60% JAL 6.66% Figure 4.1 Total Votes for Incumbent Party, Gubernatorial Elections, 1985-2004 Percentage Years Source: http2//www.cidac.org 87 Table 4.2 Gubernatorial Elections across Mexican States, 1985-2004 Incumbent Support (% votes) OLS Coefficient (S.E.) Variable Model 1 Model 2 (Fixed Effects) GSP Growth Rate 3.553" 3.949" (1.786) (1.935) Own Revenues 36.172" 70.967*** (14.200) (19.924) Federal Revenues 24.075*** 29.204*** (7.339) (9.387) Non-PRI Experience -7.638*** -47.472** (2.842) (20.976) Concurrent 1 -0.472 -0.480 (3.576) (4.844) . Divided 1 -7.859 44.745" (5.639) (7.216) Concurrent 2 -4.1 15 1 1.080 (4.548) (9.504) Divided 2 -14.640*** -12.090*** (3.320) (3.729) Constant 51.242*** 52.912*** (6.409) (1 1.998) N 112 112 Adjusted R-squared 0.4057 0.4403 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better Table 4.3 Local Legislature Elections across Mexican States, 1985-2004 Incumbent Support (%seats) OLS Coefficient (S.E.) Variable Model 1 Model 2 (Fixed Effects) GSP Growth Rate -13.115*** -15.192*** (3.273) (3.355) Own Revenues 1.474 10.127 (6-891) (7.609) Federal Revenues 18.509*** 14.650" * (3.999) (4.667) Non-PRI Experience -6.376*** -30.817*** (L612) (8.206) Concurrent l -l.301 -0.258 (1.625) (1.708) Divided l -l3.020*** -l3.875*** (3.143) (3.274) Concurrent 2 -0.961 2.304 (2.283) (2.701) Divided 2 40.153444: 94304:“ (2247) (2.303) Constant 57.825*** 67.658*** (2.699) (7.312) N 209 209 Adj. R-squared 0.4134 0.4453 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. "‘ = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better Chapter 5. Individual-Level Analysis 5.1 Introduction The findings of last chapter confirmed that, based on aggregate-level data, the classic economic voting hypothesis holds at the state level in Mexico. That is, macroeconomic indicators are linked to some degree to incumbent support in state-level elections across the Mexican states. Furthermore, the results show that even though the economic voting hypothesis holds across the Mexican states, it does so in differing degrees of intensity among the different subnational contexts. However, due to its nature, an aggregate-level model does not permit us to explore further this apparent variability in the strength of economic voting. In this regard, the model presents two main weaknesses. First, it assumes that the political and economic contexts across states are the same. Second, the model assumes that citizens across the states respond (or not) in the same way to their economic and political contexts when voting for their subnational leaders. In short, this macro-level model treats both context and voters as homogeneous, and does not distinguish variations between states. So, the question remains, what accounts for this variability in economic voting across the states? Under what conditions are voters more likely to use elections as an act of accountability? How rational is the Mexican voter after all? The analysis of this chapter makes use of pre-electoral survey data collected by the newspaper group Reforma in the Mexican states of Chiapas, Chihuahua, Jalisco, Michoacan, Nuevo Leon, and Querétaro. These states make an excellent sample because they reflect the variation across states in three main ways: geographic location, economic performance, and political experiences (Table 5.1 presents the main characteristics of this 90 sample of states). Thus, the purpose of this chapter is to expand last chapter’s findings, by switching to the micro-level analysis in order to examine more closely both the different contexts among states and individual motivations that lie behind economic voting. The advantages of such a model are numerous, including the possibility to account for multiple intervening factors such as political and socioeconomic cleavages, which are considered to be traditionally very strong in new democratic regimes. Overall, the findings of this chapter show support for the hypotheses tested here. As expected, those states with better economic performance and direct experience under opposition governments (Jalisco and Nuevo Leon) show the clearest support for the theory. Citizens in Chihuahua and Querétaro, both states with experience under panista administrations, show clear support of the theory as well. More importantly, the results of this analysis confirm that the institutional capacity of subnational government differ among states, and it has strong effects on citizens’ likelihood to be economic voters. 5.2 Theoretical Considerations In the analysis of chapter 4, I tried to explain the presence of economic voting through diverse variables, such as a state’s economic performance, a state’s level of economic decentralization, and a state’s local political environment. When analyzing gubernatorial elections, I found support for all three claims, which in short point to the conclusion that “institutions matter.” Yet, a crucial question remains: Are the findings so far accidental or have voters learned to use elections as an act of accountability? As reviewed in chapter 3, Mexican voters were constrained by an overwhelming presidential system, by powerless and, for the most part, subservient to the federal government 91 subnational leaders, and by elections that were mostly just an act of formality and symbolism. I have argued that the decentralization of political and economic powers have turned elections into an act of accountability. But, what about voters? Have they learned to make well-informed decisions when deciding whom to vote for? 15 perhaps their learning a product of their local context? The argument presented here is that they do, however, this propensity varies according to their state’s level of political and economic powers. That is, a state that has experienced alternation of power, divided government, and is able to economically detach itself —at least to some extent— from the federal government, is more likely to have a more informed citizenry that makes use of elections in a new way. When do performance evaluations become significant to citizens? So far, I have argued that adequate decentralization of power strengthens subnational institutions in such a way that elections take on a different meaning: they become an instrument of accountability for voters. So, the next question refers to once leaders institutionalize accountability in the act of elections, then what triggers voters to take into account performance evaluations? Following Diamond (1999277-93), legitimacy and regime performance are closely intertwined, particularly in the early stages of the democratization process. As democracy deepens, the legitimacy of the regime tends to depend less on performance evaluations and more on citizens’ “default” commitment to democracy. This is what Diamond refers to as “intrinsic, diffuse, or unconditional legitimacy.” As explained by Bratton, Mattes, and Gyimah-Boadi (2005242), “performance evaluations cover at least two baskets of public goods. In one basket are economic goods, like jobs, incomes, assets (for example, 92 land), consumer products, and an array of social services; in the other basket are political goods including political order, civil liberties, electoral rights, human dignity, and equality before the law.” Applying Diamond’s argument to the concept of political and economic goods, the logic followed is that citizens in new democracies expect both political and economic goods at once, and once they develop an unconditional commitment to political goods, then they will support the system, and the system’s economic performance will not put this support at risk. If I am correct in arguing that economic voting is largely a function of decentralization of political and economic powers, then it is expected that citizens living in states that have already provided them with the required political goods (or commitment to democracy) will perhaps feel more freely to express their preferences at the voting polls, because they see no threat in doing 50. Conversely, citizens living in states where it is still unclear to what level political elites are committed to democracy, citizens will be less likely to use elections as a tool of accountability. Next, I present a number of assumptions based on some specific characteristics of the states contained in the sample. On the one hand, Chiapas is a southern state, and perhaps best known to international observers for the indigenous uprising led by the Zapatista Army of National Liberation (EZLN), which started in 1994.39 During Mexico’s recent democratic transition process, Chiapas has been considered (along with Puebla, Tabasco, Guerrero, Oaxaca, and Campeche) to be fertile ground for the “survival and even strengthening of subnational authoritarian enclaves” (Cornelius 1999). With a population largely rural (57% of its active population working in agriculture, INEGI ’9 See Harvey (1999) for an analysis of the Zapatista Movement within Mexico’s democratic transition process. 93 2001) and composed by 24.7% of indigenous population (INEGI 2001), Chiapas is among the poorest states in the country. The state’s socioeconomic characteristics made it a traditional PRI stronghold, which developed a large base of support among its agricultural workers. In general, the dire economic circumstances of this sector makes it particularly vulnerable to authoritarian practices and impunity exercised to maintain electoral control. In this context, struggling citizens are assumed to be particularly susceptible to clientelist and vote buying practices. Chihuahua, just like Nuevo Leon, borders to the North with the US. The border itself presents unique characteristics compared to the rest of the nation. In general terms, the natural and intensive interactions taking place between both sides of the border create different environments. Politically, Chihuahua is a state with a comparatively long history of experience with the opposition.40 In 1992 it became the third state (after Baja California and Guanajuato) to experience alternation of power when the PAN won the governor’s office. Furthermore, in the next elections in 1998, the PRI managed to win back the govemorship. Thus, citizens living in Chihuahua are among the minority of Mexican citizens who have experienced two alternations of power (along with Nuevo Leon and Tlaxcala). Citizens in this state, according to the theoretical framework that is being tested here, are expected to be aware that different parties in power offer different styles of governing, and that elections are the mechanism through which they can express which party they prefer to have in office. The third state, Jalisco, is characterized by a large population (7% of total) that is disproportionately concentrated in Guadalajara — the third largest city in the nation (after Mexico City and Monterrey). Jalisco is largely an industrial state. It is characterized ’0 See Aziz (2000) for an in-depth account of Chihuahua’s recent political history. 94 along with Nuevo Leén, by its early progress in developing an independent press, which is expected to increase citizen’s awareness and information of public affairs. As seen earlier, there is a theoretical consensus on the need of an informed citizenship to improve the quality of a democracy. In addition to formal education, which is the single most important factor in improving cognitive awareness (Bratton, Mattes, and Gyimah-Boadi 2005:40-41), a free media contributes to the increase of people’s awareness and knowledge of public affairs. In 1995 the PAN won the govemorship, and it has kept it under control until now. Michoacan is politically best identified by being the PRD’s stronghold. Founder and long-time leader of the PRD, Cuauhtémoc Cardenas, is a native from Michoacan, as was his father and former Mexican President Lazaro Cardenas—who nationalized the oil industry in 1936 and is perhaps the most revered president in Mexican history. Before Cardenas split from the PRI in 1987, he had been Michoacan’s governor, so when he formed his own party (PRD in May of 1989), he could count on an already-built base of support in his native state. After a long struggle spanning over ten years, the PRD won its first govemorship in 2000. Nuevo Leon is the second border state in the sample. Two characteristics make this state stand out from the rest: a large, politically active business sector, and a strong, serious, and independent media. On the one hand, Nuevo Leon developed largely as an industrial state with the city of Monterrey as its economic center. As a result of the economic crisis the nation went through during the 19805, a group composed primarily of small- and medium-size entrepreneurs joined forces with the PAN to fight politically against the PRI (Mizrahi 2003; Chand 2001). The PAN won eventually in 1997, and 95 experienced in 2003 again an alternation when the PR1 won the govemorship back. The other trait that characterizes the state of Nuevo Leon is its long history of an independent media. The newspaper group Reforma started here in the 19405 with the newspaper El Norte. Finally, the state of Querétaro has become one of PAN’s steadiest electoral strongholds. It is composed by a population largely conservative, where the Catholic Church counts with a strong presence. Since 1997, the PAN won control of both the govemorship and the majority of seats in the local congress. It has kept tight control over both since then. 5.3 Hypotheses The next set of hypotheses is divided according to the two main dependent variables, namely, approval of governor and vote for the incumbent governor’s party.41 Hypothesis 1: Sociotropic Evaluations HIA proposes that individual evaluations of the governor vary positively with evaluations of the state '5 economy. H] B proposes that electoral support for the incumbent governor ’5 party will vary positively with individual evaluations of the state ’5 economy. Hypothesis 2: Pocketbook Evaluations H2A proposes that individual evaluations of the governor vary positively with the respondent’s evaluation of his/her own economy. HZB proposes that electoral support for 41 . . . . . . . . . Vote for the incumbent majorrty party 1n local congress electrons 15 not mentioned, it 15 however assumed to be included in the hypotheses related to the electoral support for governor. 96 the incumbent governor ’s party will vary positively with the respondent ’s evaluation of his/her own economy. Hypothesis 1 and 2 deal with the classic economic voting variables of sociotropic and pocketbook evaluations. The expectation is that when individuals are satisfied with the economic performance of their state, they will support the sitting government, and when they are disappointed with the state’s economic performance, they will punish the incumbent’s party. Hypothesis 3: In-Party Since the objective here is to find out where, and to what extent Mexican voters are economic voters, this hypothesis rests on a counter-argument of the referendum- voting model, which builds on the premise that “the responsibility of managing the state economy is laid at the feet of the governor” (Atkeson and Partin 19952 100). The fundamental logic of the referendum model implies that individual voters send messages to the central government when evaluating the performance of subnational leaders. However, economic voters are expected to be able to distinguish between layers of government when they assess their government’s economic performance. That is, when economic voters are casting a vote at the state level, they are supposed to be evaluating their governor’s administration performance, not their president’s. The approach defended here assumes that voters recognize the independent policy-making role played by governors. H3A proposes that voters living in in-party states will show less gubernatorial approval. Along the same line, H3B proposes that the probability to vote for the incumbent party decreases if the incumbent governor’s party is the same as the president’s party. 97 Hypothesis 4: Fiscal Autonomy H4A expects gubernatorial approval to be higher in the more decentralized states. Accordingly, H48 expects that electoral support for the incumbent governor ’s party will be higher the more decentralized a state is. Within a country, economic evaluations are expected to be significant in varying degrees, according to the different levels of clarity of responsibility that each state develops (Powell and Whitten 1993). Economic evaluations are expected to be significant the higher the clarity of responsibility a state has. When political conditions help voters associate the candidate of the incumbent party with the outgoing government or, to put it another way, when the context “eases the attribution of responsibility,” economic assessments should have a greater impact on incumbent vote choice. The role governors play in state and national economic management combined to their increasing level of public visibility suggests that governors should be held accountable for state economic performance, especially in the more decentralized (fiscally autonomous) states (Chihuahua, Jalisco, Nuevo Leon, and Querétaro). Conversely, the less decentralized states (Chiapas and Michoacan) are expected to exhibit the reverse behavior. 5.4 Data and Model The hypotheses are explored on the basis of survey data collected by the newspaper Reforma in six states prior to gubernatorial elections between 2000 and 2004. Each survey was conducted on a representative sample of the population of each state through face-to-face interviews. The sample size of the six surveys ranges from 840 to 1205 respondents (Table 5.1). The assembled data set offers enough variation in 98 economic and political conditions across subnational units to provide a robust test of the hypotheses. As shown in Table 5.1, subnational economic performance varies from one state to another. The states included in the analysis represent about 24 percent of the country’s total population and 24 percent of its GDP. It is clear that regional economic performance differs from the overall national performance, as well as across states. In addition, the data set provides two cases where the incumbent governor does not belong to the president’s party (Michoacan, Chihuahua) at the time of the survey. This is especially important to test the effects of in-party. In addition to variations across the subnational units selected for the analysis, there are important differences with respect to the six states. As observed earlier, Mexico initiated its process of political and economic decentralization. during the 19805 and more so during the 19905. However, the extent to which these processes in each individual state have led to the effective decentralization of the federal regime varies from one state to another, especially in terms of financial decentralization. Figure 5.1 shows the varying degrees of subnational capacity to generate own revenues. Within an average taken over 2000 and 2002, Chihuahua is clearly the state with the highest capacity to produce its own revenues, with subnational government revenues accounting for almost 20 percent of the state’s total revenues. Comparing this sample with all states and excluding Mexico City, Chihuahua is still the most financially autonomous (national mean=l 1.5) Dependent Variables ’2 a) Gubernatorial Approval This variable measures individual approval of the incumbent governor, as expressed by the respondent when asked to evaluate in retrospective the incumbent ’2 The complete list of the questions used and their recoding is included in the Appendix B. 99 governor’s job. The item could take four values: disapproves completely, disapproves some, approves some, and approves completely.43 b) Incumbent Support in Gubernatorial Elections This is a binary variable that reflects individual vote choice in gubernatorial elections. It takes a value of one when the respondent voted for the incumbent governor’s party, zero otherwise. In all six states, the question used in the analysis asked respondents to cast their vote for governor in a ballot box that provided by the interviewer. c) Incumbent Support in State Legislature’s Elections Vote choice in local legislature’s elections, takes a value of one when the individual voted for the incumbent local congress’ majority party, zero otherwise. Chiapas is not included in this model, because it only held elections for governor in 2000. Independent Variables of Main Interest a) Sociotropic and Pocketbook Evaluations The independent variables of most interest included in the model consist of two individual retrospective44 economic assessments: the respondent’s evaluation of the economy in his or her state, as well as his or her own economic situation at the end of the incumbent administration. Fortunately, the surveys included for the most part the same questions across states.45 The sociotropic item was measured with the question asking respondents to assess the performance of their state economy. This question had three ossible answers: “im roved,” “remained the same,” or “worsened.” The ocketbook P ‘3 In the case of Chiapas, the choices were three: good government, indifferent, and bad government. In order to get four categories, the “Don’t know” and “Did not respond” responses were recoded into “Disapprove some.” 4‘ Unfortunately, only the most recent survey, Chihuahua, included a question on prospective economic evaluation. ’5 In Chihuahua, respondents were asked to evaluate the overall condition of their state under the incumbent governor, rather than specifically the economy of the state. 100 evaluation was measured with the item asking respondents about their past personal situation, having the same three response choices as the sociotropic item. b) Local Electoral Environment In order to explain to some extent the variation across states, a state-level variable was included in the model. This dummy variable takes a value of one when the incumbent governor’s party is the same as the president’s party in turn, zero otherwise. It is used in interactions with the sociotropic and pocketbook variables to compare the impact of these variables on incumbent support in both in- and out-party states. Control Variables a) Partisan Identity The model includes a control variable for party preferences. This variable consists of the respondent’s self-declared party identification or preference. In all four states, the original question asked “Generally speaking, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?,” which refers to each of the three major parties (PRI, PAN, and PRD). The answers included “very and some priista,” “very and some panista,” or “very and some perredista,” and they were recoded into a dummy variable taking the value one if the respondent claimed to identify with the incumbent governor’s political party. Traditionally, partisanship has been the most powerful predictor of vote choice in the Mexican electorate. It is assumed that the concept includes the effects of presidential approval. b) Political Knowledge and Interest Political knowledge is represented in this analysis by two kinds of questions. First, the respondent’s level of education, which was recoded into three categories 101 identifying individuals with “primary level completed,” “secondary/technical level completed,” and “some university education or better.” The secont indicator of political knowledge was taken from a question asking the respondent whether s/he knows when the next elections are taking place. Interest was taken from a question asking respondents how interested they are in the political campaigns going on for the next election. c) Locality and Income Finally, two dummy variables are included to control for the socioeconomic status of the respondents. Locality took a value of one when the respondent lives in an urban or mixed area, zero when the respondent lives in a rural area. Income was used to control for the income level of the respondents; it was recoded intro three categories identifying individuals earning “0 to 4,000 pesos”, “4,001 to 12,000 pesos”, and “12,001 & more pesos.” It is expected that individuals living in an urban area, will be more likely to vote for the incumbent party. Income is also expected to have a positive coefficient. In order to test the hypotheses the analysis relies on an additive model of individual governor’s approval and vote choice in gubernatorial and local legislature’s elections. The general model for vote choice can be resumed as follows: Gubernatorial Approval 1 = 130 + [31 State Economic Performance + [32 Personal Economic Performance + 133 Partisan Identity + e, Incumbent Support,- = 130 +13, State Economic Performance + [32 Personal Economic Performance + [33 Partisan Identity + e, 5.5 Analysis and Results The statistical analysis relies on both the ordered probit and probit regression methods. First, the results are presented separately by state for each of the three 102 dependent variables (Tables 5.1-5.3). Tables 5.4 to 5.6 contain the results of the merged data sets. Table 5.2 presents the results for the model explaining gubernatorial approval. The classic economic voting hypothesis is overall consistently supported across the six states, although some variation can be observed across the states and between the two measures of economic voting. First, sociotropic evaluations are clearly the strongest in Jalisco and Nuevo Leon, even stronger than their respective party id coefficients. Chiapas, Chihuahua, and Querétaro also strongly support HlA, suggesting that for voters in these states, their state’s economic performance is quite important when evaluating their governor’s performance. Michoacan is the only state where this variable is not significant. Second, pocketbook evaluations (H2A) are statistically significant in all cases. In Querétaro, this indicator has more explanatory power than the sociotropic one. In Chiapas, Chihuahua, and Nuevo Leon the coefficient is clearly weaker than the sociotropic one. Partisan identity is the only variable that is consistently significant across all states. Table 5.3 presents the results of the same model for the dependent variable of incumbent support in gubernatorial elections. The results are clearly more mixed than the one in the previous table. First, Chihuahua, Jalisco, and Nuevo Le6n present again the strongest support for the economic voting sociotropic argument. The results in Querétaro are significant still, but weaker than in the previous cases. Again, the pocketbook coefficient is stronger than the sociotropic one. The coefficients of Chiapas and Michoacan do not reach significance in any of the cases. Second, the pocketbook 103 hypothesis is significant only in the cases of Nuevo Leon and Queretaro. Third, party identity remains strongly significant across all cases. Table 5.4 presents the results of the model looking at incumbent support in state legislature’s elections. Overall, this model shows weaker support for the economic voting hypothesis. Again, the economic voting hypothesis is the strongest in Jalisco and Nuevo Leon when observing the results for the sociotropic variable, although comparatively much weaker than in the other models. Chihuahua and Querétaro are significant as well. Michoacan, consistent with the other results, is not significant. When looking at the results for the pocketbook hypothesis, the results present weaker explanatory power for the economic voting argument. Chihuahua does not reach significance at all. Only Nuevo Leon and Querétaro present support for the argument. For Querétaro, consistent with the other models, the pocketbook argument appears to have stronger explanatory power than the sociotropic one. The results in Michoacan are unexpected, because the coefficient is significant but negative. Party identity remains the one variable consistently significant and the strongest. Table 5.5 presents the first results of the merged data set for the dependent variable of gubernatorial support. The table includes the results for three models. Model 1 is the same model previously used with the individual states. The economic voting hypothesis is strongly supported in both the sociotropic and the pocketbook hypotheses across the three models. Consistent with previous results, the sociotropic hypothesis is' supported clearly stronger. Model 2 includes the state-level variable in-party to help account for state—level factors. As discussed earlier, my intuition is that economic voters living in states where the governor belongs to the president’s party, will be more likely to 104 approve or support less the incumbent governor, which would be a sign that such voters are able to distinguish between both layers of government. The results of Model 2 support this hypothesis. Model 3 includes an interaction term composed of the in-party variable and the sociotropic and pocketbook evaluations. The expectation is that economic voters living in in-party states and with positive economic performance evaluations, will be less likely to approve or support the incumbent governor. This hypothesis is supported in Model 3. Again, across all models, partisan identity is consistently significant. Table 5.6 presents the merged results for the dependent variable of incumbent electoral support. The same three models are included here. Again, the results show consistent support for the sociotropic hypothesis across the three models. The results for the pocketbook hypothesis are more mixed. The hypothesis is supported in Models 1 and 2, but not so in Model 3. The in-party variable is significant and in the expected direction, as it is the case with the interaction term. Finally, Table 5.7 presents the results for the dependent variable of incumbent support in state legislature’s elections. Similarly with the results of incumbent gubernatorial result, the economic voting hypothesis is consistently supported with the sociotropic argument. The in-party variable is significant and in the expected direction, however, the interaction term does not reach significance. 5.6 Conclusion The current chapter explored the relationship between individual economic assessments and gubernatorial approval and vote choice on the basis of survey data 105 collected. in six Mexican states. Overall, the results presented in this chapter show support for the economic voting argument explored here, but to different degrees across the states. The results offer clear support for the retrospective sociotropic hypothesis. The findings suggest that governors are held accountable for state-level economic performance. More precisely, positive assessments about the state’s economy increase the likelihood of approving and/or voting for the governor’s party. Both variables of main interest—an individual’s evaluation of state-level and personal economic perfonnance— are found to impact differently across the states under study. The variability across the states, however, supports the theoretical expectations. First, economic voting is clearly the strongest in Chihuahua, Jalisco, and Nuevo Leon, the three states that have experienced alternation of power. Both Chihuahua and Nuevo Leon have experienced in fact two alternations. To a lesser degree, but also consistently, citizens in Querétaro are economic voters as well. The fact that governors are evaluated on the basis of state economic performance in Jalisco and Nuevo Leon, more than in the other states, suggests that political decentralization is associated with increased democratic accountability. More decentralized regimes seem to provide political incentives for good subnational economic management and public service provision. This shows that governors that manage the economy well can actually gain electoral benefits from managing their state more efficiently, while those who fail to generate good economic performance run the risk of losing support. 106 The findings of this chapter support the argument that gubernatorial approval reflects a combination of both national and state-level evaluations (Svoboda 1995; King 2001). Both dependent variables used in the analysis, gubernatorial approval and vote choice present clear evidence that national-level factors have strong explanatory power. For instance, partisan identity appears with stronger support in results for vote choice. Here, the evidence supporting the economic voting theory are weaker, but still significant in the expected states. States with higher levels of dependency on the federal government (such as Chiapas) are expected to depend mostly on partisan loyalty. The different results between approval and vote choice should be further examined. 107 can States, 1970-2004 ext Figure 3.5 Municipal-Level Competition (Holbrook- Van Dunk Index), M I 1970-1989 I 1990-2004 _ — —-_er — — — - ‘ ,L wruu.nmymfx. W’ . _— _— _— _— _— —t—|_"W- . _ — _ — -———;._W~ _1_——-.W_ ‘—-—— Wm — - . MW 1——— __- 1_1___ _—— _ - - _ I v.8”mwflm _— -h-II— “*NWM WW. ——_ __—_.... Kqu‘xu TM . . - =_ ”I ~ I-.:..r --—-— t‘SW‘WW-vlv -. .wm~ 90 80 I I I I I I I I C Q Q C O Q C O F VD If) V M N '— 9” 3,9- «We a e 95 e o o e 4 o s e 108 Source: Table 4. Figure 5.1 State ’5 Own Revenues, Average Percentage 2000-2002 NUEVO LEON QUERETARO MICHOACAN 223" " " " "’-"~" ““300 .. . CHIHUAHUA i 1 CHIAPAS I t 1 3 i I l . . 1 | 1 I I , . 0.00 2.00 4.00 6.00 8.00 10.00 12.00 14.00 16.00 18.00 20.00 Percentage Source: INEGI 109 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 State 1 weaned 1 1 F‘ Figure 5.2 Mexican States, Own Revenues (% of total state revenue), Average 1989-2003 110 Table 5.2 Gubernatorial Approval, Selected Mexican States (Ordered Probit Analysis) Nuevo Chiagts Chihuahua Jalisco Michoacan Lec’m Querétaro State Economy .474*** 515*" l.164*** .051 1.478*** 182*” (.078) (.055) (.065) (.063) (.145) (.060) Personal Finances 195*“ .152“ n.a. .184*** 185*" .448*** (.073) (.060) (.068) (.061) (.072) Party ID .649*** .744*** .479*** .468*** .478*** .438*** (.088) (.083) (.082) (.085) (.097) (.097) Interest .131 ** -.001 -.024 -.020 .007 .079 (.065) (.064) (.062) (.056) (.064) (.064) Knowledge .038 .1 17" .036 -.006 .063 .1 14 (.047) (.053) (.047) (.043) (.067) (.071) Education -.104 .012 .027 -.009 .092* -.027 (.064) (.059) (.055) (.025) (.054) (.061) Income -.1 12 -.094 .056 -.135** 219*" .052 (.083) (.070) (.065) (.067) (.073) (.075) Urban (=1) -.185** -.014 .042 .048 -.126 .097 (.088) (.1 17) (.089) (.086) (.185) (.092) Log Likelihood -794.09 -829.75 -763.75 -872.93 -689.88 -681.66 Pseudo R-Squared .091 l .1374 .2519 .0262 .1422 .0957 N 840 1000 1205 1008 1200 855 Cut 1 .496 1.139 -.922 2.273 .707 (.259) (.235) (.224) (.450) (.285) Cut 2 2.146 3.947 .987 5.096 2.824 (.265) (.267) (.224) (.461) (.298) Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. 111 Table 5.3 Vote Choice in Gubernatorial Elections, Selected Mexican States (Probit Analysis) Nuevo Chiapas Chihuahua Jalisco Michoacan Leon Querétaro State Economy .089 299*" .475*** .092 519*" .131* (.095) (.065) (.061) (.086) (.186) (.074) Personal Finances .067 .088 n.a. -.130 .355*** .312*** (.095) (.072) (.091) (.076) (.088) Party 1D 1857*" 1477*" l.470*** 2039*“ 2026*" 1.531 *** (.1 10) (.097) (.089) (.034) (.1 10) (.l 13) Interest .137 .034 .044 .109 .01 1 .157* (.087) (.075) (.070) (.079) (.082) (.081) Knowledge -.068 .054 -.002 .013 .109 -.040 (.062) (.064) (.052) (.059) (.085) (.087) Education -.089 .141” .033 .039 .123* 205*“ (.087) (.070) (.061) (.034) (.065) (.076) Income .046 -.140* .046 -.252*** .066 .008 (.109) (.084) (.074) (.093) (.090) (.094) Urban (=1) -.006 -.041 .100 .086 -.056 .074 (.117) (.138) (.099) (.119) (.234) (.115) Constant -1.478*** -1.577*** -2.21*** -l.123*** -3.551*** -2.389*** (.417) (.315) (.272) (.302) (.575) (.360) N 840 1000 1205 1008 1200 855 Pseudo R-Squared .3369 .2585 .2772 .3493 .3804 .2747 Log Likelihood -364.21 -513.92 -590.56 -397.62 -433.04 -392.16 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. 112 Table 5.4 Vote Choice in Local Legislature Elections, Selected Mexican States (Probit Analysis) Nuevo Chihuahua Jalisco Michoacan Leon Querétaro State Economy 274*” 350*" .101 .434“ .168" (.066) (.058) (.080) (.173) (.074) Personal Finances .006 n.a. -.184** 258*“ .302*** (.072) (.085) (.075) (.088) Party 1D 1513*” 1.175*** 1585*” 1902*“ 1333*" (.096) (.085) (.101) (.106) (.1 10) Interest .037 -.045 .054 -.053 .098 (.075) (.066) (.073) (.081) (.081) Knowledge .043 -.059 .053 .083 .062 (.064) (.050) (.055) (.085) (.090) Education .004 .012 .040 127* .167” (.070) (.058) (.031) (.065) (.075) lncome -.103 * .086 .008 .001 -.091 (.084) (.070) (.085) (.089) (.094) Urban (=1) .005 .029 .040 .007 .263 (.136) (.094) (.111) (.229) (.116) Constant -l.326*** 1.457*** -l.214*** -2.963*** -2.581*** (.315) (.254) (.287) (.541) (.369) N 1000 1205 1008 1200 855 Pseudo R-Squared .2608 .1855 .2273 .3491 .2413 Log Likelihood -51 1.90 -663.97 -474.87 -441.34 -393.96 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. 113 Table 5.5 Gubernatorial Approval, Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set (Ordered Probit Analysis) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 State Economy .473*** 463*" .547*** (.027) (.027) (.034) Personal Finances .105*** .140*** .120*** (.026) (.027) (.042) Party ID 638*" 609*" .607*** (.036) (.036) (.037) Interest .009 .036 .025 (.025) (.026) (.026) Knowledge .055“ 096*" 099*” (.022) (.022) (.022) Urban (=1) -.073*"‘ .056“ .049 (.031) (.033) (.034) Education .004 -.035** -.035" (.017) (.017) (.017) Income -.042 .003 .008 (.028) (.029) (.029) lnparty -.439*** -.229* (.036) (.123) State Economy*lnparty -. 102* "‘ (.045) Personal Finances“ lnparty .013 (.054) N 4903 4903 4784 Cut 1 .069 .132 .266 (.107) (.107) (.125) Cut 2 (2.006) 2.080 2.206 (.109) .110 (.127) Cut 3 2.913 3.029 3.156 (.113) .114 (.131) Log Likelihood 4936.98 -4863.01 -4754.53 LR Chi-Squared 852.78 1000.72 1017.43 Pseudo R-Squared .0795 .0933 .0967 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .l. ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. Merged data set does not include Jalisco. 114 Table 5.6 Vote Choice in Gubernatorial Elections, Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set (Probit Analysis) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Sociotropic 222*" .21 1‘“M .274*** (.036) (.036) (.045) Pocketbook .102*** .121 *** -.054 (.035) (.036) (.055) Party 10 1826*" 1813*" 1795*” (.046) (.046) (.047) Interest .047 .062 .059* (.034) (.034) (.035) Date .014 .032 .024 (.029) (.029) (.030) Locality -.025 .038 .035 (.042) (.044) (.046) Education .055" .035 .036 (.022) (.023) (.023) lncome -.034 -.01 1 -.01 1 (.03 8) (.038) (.039) lnparty -.220*** -.562*"'* (.047) (.168) State Economy“ lnparty -.107* (.062) Personal F inances*lnparty 300*“ (.072) Constant -1.802*** -1.829*** -l.599*** (.144) (.145) (.165) N 4903 4903 4784 Log Likelihood -2180.90 -2169.98 -2116.74 LR Chi-Squared 1978.28 2000.12 1966.96 Pseudo R—Squared .3120 0.3155 .3172 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. Merged data set includes all four states. 115 Table 5. 7 Vote Choice in Local Legislature ’s Elections, Selected Mexican States, Merged Data Set (Probit Analysis) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Sociotropic 238*" 225*" .256*** (.038) (.038) (.047) Pocketbook .059 .080" -.1 13** (.03 8) (.038) (.054) Party ID 1663*" 1642*“ 1.616*** (.050) (.050) (.051) Interest -.003 .019 .010* (.037) (.037) (.038) Date .049 .082" .081" (.033) (.033) (.033) Locality .084 .1 12 .083 (.060) (.060) (.061) Education .071 ** .048" .050" (.023) (.023) (.023) Income -.070* -.024 -.024 (.041) (.042) (.042) lnparty -.276*** -.999*** (.049) (.202) State Economy" lnparty .001 (.089) Personal Finances“ lnparty .373*** (078) Constant -1.796*** -l.865*** -1.513*** (.155) (.156) (.173) N 4063 4063 4012 Log Likelihood -1880. 10 -1864.58 -1831.68 LR Chi-Squared 1390.58 1421.63 1430.99 Pseudo R-Squared .2700 0.2760 .2809 Notes: Standard errors are listed in parentheses. * = statistically significant at .1, ** = statistically significant at .05, and *** = statistically significant at .01 or better. Chiapas is not included. 116 Chapter 6. Conclusion There is an overall scholarly consensus that the Mexican democratic transition process culminated with the alternation of power in 2000, when the PRI was unseated by President Fox’s PAN. Having observed these events unfold firsthand, and seeing expectations and hopes rise among citizens, the question that underlies this dissertation took form in the following way: to what extent were these national-level political changes reaching Mexican citizens? As I have stressed so far, one of the PRI-regime’s major shortcomings was its lack of responsiveness to the public. For the most part, the basic form of political participation—elections—had no real meaning to citizens, beyond being for the most part a ritual of transfer of power within the PRI. So, within this new electoral context, in which Mexico could finally be labeled an electoral democracy, did the government turn accountable to its citizens? In other words, and as I ask in the introduction of this dissertation, to what extent does the label “new democracy” guarantee working mechanisms of accountability? Without doubt, establishing effective circuits of accountability between politicians and electoral constituencies constitutes a latent challenge not only in Mexico, but in new democracies more generally. Exploring this question by looking at the Mexican states took me invariably to hypothesize that democracy had reached citizens to different degrees, that is, state governments vary according to their individual experiences. Within different contexts, elections acquire different meanings. To the extent that state-level political leaders become autonomous from the central government, accountability increases. The different hypotheses in this study had the overall purpose to test under what conditions do 117 elections work as an instrument of accountability. The results support in different ways the underlying argument that elections acquire a power of accountability in function of a state’s level of political and economic decentralization. In order to undertake this type of analysis, I had to answer one prior question: Is the economy part of the voting calculus among the Mexican electorate? The macro-level analysis in Chapter 4 looks at this question, and the findings show evidence that a state’s economic performance has been indeed part of the voting decision in gubernatorial elections during the last nineteen years. Once this prior question had been answered, it was possible to look at the effects of political and economic decentralization on electoral behavior. According to the expectations put forward here, both factors probed to have effects on electoral behavior. States performing better in economic terms, with higher levels of economic autonomy vis-a-vis the federal government, and with experience under a non-PRI government, probed to be more likely to have economic voters among its population, who in turn are capable of holding the government accountable for its performance on election day. The second part of the analysis took on the task of exploring the apparent variations across the states by using micro-level data. Clearly, the results are limited in several ways, and need to be further expanded, but the findings did support in different ways the key argument of this work. Overall, the likelihood of Mexicans being economic voters depends on the political and economic contexts they live in. The results of the statistical analyses undertaken here show support for the economic voting theory, but there is visible variation in the strength of the theory across the states. One important result that came to the surface in this analysis is the distinction between approval and 118 vote choice. In general, the theory appeared consistently stronger in regard with approval. A reason could be that respondent’s feel freer to express their opinion about the sitting government when they are “just” being asked whether they approve or not of the government’s performance. On the other hand, when asked for whom they would actually vote, then voters seem to go back to “traditional” cleavages, mostly to their partisan identity. However, based on the findings of chapter 5, it is safe to say that some form of economic voting is taking place in the Mexican states, with stronger evidence in those states that are both economically better off and have experienced rule under a party other than the PRI. These findings have different implications for the study of the quality of new democracies. First, and perhaps this dissertation’s most valuable contribution, this study sheds light on the dynamics taking place at the subnational level in a new democracy. It shows that democratization reaches citizens unevenly, and that the manner in which they experience democracy is a function to a great extent of state-level factors. For one, the nature of the opposition is of crucial importance. As argued by Manin, Przeworski, and Stokes (1999:48), “Citizens have two agents, not just one: the incumbents who govern and the opposition that wants to become the government. . .The opposition has incentives to monitor the government ant to inform (truthfully or not) voters about the performance of the incumbents.” In fact, opposition parties constitute a key element in developing partisan competition, which in turn causes citizens to be more attentive to politics (Muller and Seligson 1994). Furthermore, this dissertation joins the claim developed in different forms by scholars of Mexican politics (Cornelius 1999; Fox 1994; Lawson 2000), and which was 119 so clearly put by Hiskey and Bowler (2005:67) who see the local context “as a critical frontline for these struggling democracies, one where support for and engagement with a democratic system of government can either be fostered or frustrated.” In other words, it would be a mistake to see the nation through the national-level changes, and make assumptions based on such. Local politics matter, and they produce different types of electorate as well. Second, by studying economic voting at the subnational level in a new democracy, this study contributes to the broad field of electoral behavior. Studying the way in which voters elect their leaders is essential to understanding the functioning of any democracy. This exercise becomes more relevant in nascent democracies, where voters are “learning democracy” (Anderson and Dodd 2005). The findings of this dissertation shed light on this learning process, one which is widely acknowledged but difficult to operationalize. Overall, this dissertation probes the broader applicability of the theory, but it also warns on the importance of taking into account variations in the economic and political contexts. Finally, these findings have direct implications for the study of accountability in new democratic contexts. Both the aggregate and individual-level analyses suggested that opposition (or non-PRI) governments develop different styles of governing that involve most of the times greater communication with citizens (greater transparency and access to information). These conclusions are very positive in regard to the development of a culture of accountability, which was not fostered during the one-party regime. They suggest that accountability has greater chances of appearing and staying, when it becomes part of the political survival strategy of subnational leaders. That is, elections 120 will be used by voters as an instrument of accountability to the extent that subnational political leaders are in need of their local constituents—a practice that is quite new in Mexico. 121 APPENDICES 122 Appendix A. States and Election Years, Chapter 4 Table A. Gubernatorial Elections, Mexican States, 1985-2004 Election State year State Election year State Election year AGS 1986 H00 1987 SLP 1985 A08 1992 HGO 1993 SLP 1991 AGS 1998 H00 1999 8 LP 1997 AGS 2004 1 AL 1988 SLP 2003 BC 1989 I AL 1995 SIN 1986 BC 1995 J AL 2000 SIN 1992 BC 2001 MEX 1987 SIN 1998 BCS 1987 MEX 1993 SIN 2004 BCS 1993 MEX 1999 SON 1985 BC S 1999 MICH 1986 SON 1991 CAMP 1985 MIC H 1992 SON 1997 CAMP 1991 MIC H 1995 SON 2003 CAMP 1997 MICH 2001 SON 1985 CAMP 2003 MOR 1988 SON 1991 COAH 1 987 MOR 1994 SON 1 997 COAH 1 993 MOR 2000 SON 2003 COAH 1 999 NAY 1987 TAB 1988 COL 1985 NAY 1993 TAB 1994 COL 1991 NAY 1999 TAB 2001 COL 1 997 N L 1 985 TAM 1 986 COL 2003 NL 1991 TAM 1992 CHIS 1988 N L 1997 TAM 1998 CHIS 1994 N L 2003 TAM 2004 CHIS 2000 OAX 1986 TLAX 1986 C HIH 1 986 OAX 1 992 TLAX 1 992 C HIH 1992 OAX 1998 TLAX 1998 C HIH 1998 OAX 2004 TLAX 2004 C HIH 2004 PUE 1986 VER 1986 D00 1 986 PU E 1992 VER 1992 D00 1992 PU E 1998 VER 1998 DGO 1998 PUE 2004 VER 2004 D60 2004 QRO 1985 YUC 1987 GTO 1985 QRO 1991 YUC 1993 GTO 1991 QRO 1997 YUC 1995 GTO 1995 QRO 2003 YUC 2001 GTO 2000 QROO 1987 ZAC 1 986 GRO 1986 QROO 1993 ZAC 1992 GRO 1993 QROO 1999 ZAC 1998 GRO 1 999 ZAC 2004 DF 2000 Source: IF E. 123 Table B. State Legislature Elections, Mexican States, 1985-2004 Election Electionl Election Election Election Electionl State Year State Year State Year State Year State Year State Year AGS 1985 CHIH 1985 MICH 1985 QRO 1987 QRO 1987 TAM 1986 AGS 1988 CHIH 1988 MICH 1988 QRO 1 990 QRO 1990 TAM 1 989 AGS 1991 CHIH 1991 MICH 1991 QRO 1993 QRO 1993 TAM 1992 AGS 1994 CHIH 1994 MIC H 1994 QRO 1996 QRO 1 996 TAM 1 995 AGS 1997 CHIH 1997 MICH 1997 QRO 1999 QRO 1 999 TAM 1 998 AGS 2000 CHIH 2000 MICH 2000 QRO 2002 QRO 2002 TAM 2000 AGS 2003 C HIH 2003 MICH 2003 QROO 1986 QROO 1986 TAM 2003 BC 1985 DGO 1985 MOR 1987 QROO 1989 QROO 1989 TLAX 1 985 BC 1 988 DGO 1988 MOR 1 990 QROO 1992 QROO 1 992 TLAX 1988 BC 1991 DGO 1991 MOR 1993 QROO 1995 QROO 1995 TLAX 1991 BC 1 994 DGO 1 994 MOR 1 996 QROO 1 998 QROO 1 998 TLAX 1994 BC 1997 DGO 1997 MOR 1999 QROO 2001 QROO 2001 TLAX 1997 BC 2000 DGO 2000 MOR 2002 SLP 1986 SLP 1986 TLAX 2000 BC 2003 DGO 2003 NAY 1986 SLP 1989 SLP 1989 TLAX 2003 BC S 1986 GTO 1987 NAY 1989 SLP 1992 SLP 1992 VER 1985 BCS 1989 GTO 1990 NAY 1992 SLP 1996 SLP 1996 VER 1988 BCS 1992 GTO 1993 NAY 1995 SLP 1999 SLP 1999 VER 1991 BCS 1995 GTO 1996 NAY 1998 S LP 2002 SLP 2002 VER 1994 BCS 1998 GTO 1999 NAY 2001 SIN 1985 SIN 1985 VE R 1997 BCS 2001 GTO 2002 NL 1987 SIN 1988 SIN 1988 VER 2000 CAMP 1985 GRO 1986 NL 1990 SIN 1991 SIN 1991 VER 2003 CAMP 1988 GRO 1989 NL 1993 SIN 1994 SIN 1994 YUC 1987 CAMP 1991 GRO 1992 NL 1996 SIN 1997 SIN 1997 YUC 1990 CAMP 1993 GRO 1995 NL 1999 SIN 2000 SIN 2000 YUC 1993 CAMP 1996 GRO 1998 NL 2002 SIN 2003 SIN 2003 YUC 1994 CAMP 1999 GRO 2001 OAX 1985 SON 1987 SON 1987 YUC 1995 CAMP 2002 HGO 1986 OAX 1988 SON 1990 SON 1990 YUC 1 997 COAH 1987 HGO 1989 OAX 1991 SON 1993 SON 1993 YUC 2000 COAH 1990 HGO 1992 OAX 1994 SON 1996 SON 1996 YUC 2003 C OAH 1993 HGO 1 995 OAX 1997 SON 1999 SON 1999 ZAC 1985 COAH 1996 HGO 1998 OAX 2000 SON 2002 SON 2002 ZAC 1988 COAH 1998 HGO 2001 OAX 2003 TAB 1985 TAB 1985 ZAC 1991 COAH 2001 J AL 1985 PUE 1986 TAB 1988 TAB 1988 ZAC 1994 COL 1987 1 AL 1988 PU E 1989 TAB 1991 TAB 1991 ZAC 1997 COL 1990 J AL 1991 PU E 1992 TAB 1994 TAB 1994 ZAC 2000 COL 1993 J AL 1994 PU E 1995 TAB 1997 TAB 1997 ZAC 2003 COL 1996 JAL 1997 PU E 1997 TAB 1999 TAB 1999 DE 1987 COL 1999 JAL 2000 PUE 2000 TAB 2002 TAB 2002 DF 1990 COL 2002 JAL 2002 PU E 2003 DP 1993 CHIS 1987 MEX 1986 DF 1996 CHIS 1990 MEX 1989 DF 1999 CHIS 1994 MEX 1992 DF 2002 CHIS 1997 MEX 1995 CHIS 2000 MEX 1999 CHIS 2003 MEX 2002 Source: [F E. 124 Appendix B. Question Wording and Coding, Chapter 5 Variables from pre-electoral surveys collected by Reforma in Chiapas, Chihuahua, Jalisco, Michoacan, Nuevo Leon, and Querétaro. CHIAPAS Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PRI); 0=Not Incumbent (Entregar boleta con candidatos a1 entrevistado y preguntar): Le voy a entregar una boleta con los nombres de los candidatos a Gobemador. Si hoy hubiera elecciones para Gobemador del estado, gpor quie'n votaria usted? (Pedir que marque su voto en la boleta y solicitar que esta se deposite en la urna) Vote Choice in Local Legislature Elections Not asked in Chiapas. Gubernatorial Approval [In general, how do you rate Governor Roberto Albores Guillén’s administration?] 1. Good job 2. Poor job 3. Neither good nor bad 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Poor job, 2 + 4=Neither good nor bad, 3=Good job En general, gusted considera que el Gobiemo de Roberto Albores Guillén ha sido un buen gobiemo 0 ha sido un mal gobiemo? 1. Buen gobiemo 2. Mal gobiemo 3. Ni bueno ni malo 4. No sabe/No contesto State Economy [How do you rate economic conditions in the state compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Stayed the same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2 + 4=Stayed the same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que la situacion economica del estado mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 125 1. Mejoré 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances . [How do you rate your personal economic conditions compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Stayed the same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2 + 4=Stayed the same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacién personal mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Party ID [Do you consider yourself ...(priista, panista, or perredista)? Very much or somewhat?) 1. Very 2. Somewhat 3. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PRI) [includes “very priista” and “somewhat priista”], O=Not Incumbent gSe considera usted como muy (PRIISTA / PANISTA / PERREDISTA) o algo (PRIISTA / PANISTA / PERREDISTA)? 1.Muy 2. Algo 3. No sabe/No contesto Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial elections taking place in the state?] 1. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2+3+5)=Some; 3=A lot gQue’ tan interesado esta usted en las campafias de los candidatos a la gubematura del estado: 126 l. Mucho 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubematurial elections will take place in the state?] 1. Mentioned exact date 2. Mentioned incomplete date 3. Does not remember 4. Does not know Recoded: 1 (3+4)=Does not know; 2=Incomplete; 3=Complete gMe podria decir la fecha en que se llevaran a cabo las elecciones para Gobemador del Estado, 0 en este momento no recuerda? 1. Menciono fecha completa 2. Mencioné fecha incompleta 3. No recuerda 4. No sabe Education [What is the highest level of education you have completed?] 1=No formal schooling 2. Primary schooling 3. Secondary/technical schooling 4. High school/equivalent 5. University and more 6. Did not answer Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University gHasta que afio estudio usted? gCual es su ultimo grado de estudios? 1. No tiene estudios 2. Primaria 3. Secundaria/Técnica 4. Preparatoria/Equivalente 5. Universidad o mas 6. No contesto Income [How much money do you (and your household together) earn per month?] 1. Between $0 and $1,000 2. Between $1,001 and $2,000 3. Between $2,001 and $4,000 4. Between $4,001 and $6,000 5. Between $6,001 and $8,000 127 6. Between $8,001 and $12,000 7. Between $12,001 and $16,000 8. Between $16,001 and $20,000 9. Over $21,000 10. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Between $0-$4,000; 2=$4,001-12,000; 3=Over $12,001 Entre todas las personas que viven con usted, gaproximadamente cuanto ganan a1 mes? 1. De $0 a $1,000 2. De $1,001 a $2,000 3. De $2,001 a $4,000 4. De $4,001 a $6,000 5. De $6,001 a $8,000 6. De $8,001 a $12,000 7. De $12,001 a $16,000 8. De $16,001 a $20,000 9. Mas de $21,000 10. No sabe/No contesto Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Rura1] Tipo de localidad: 1. Urbano 2. Rural CHIHUAHUA Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PRI); 0=Not Incumbent (Desprender boleta con candidatos a Gobemador) Con esta boleta no oficial y que es 3610 para propésitos de esta encuesta, digame por favor, si hoy hubiera elecciones para Gobemador de Chihuahua, [,pOI' quién votaria usted? (Pida que deposite 1a boleta en la uma) Vote Choice, Local Legislature [(Hand out ballot containing ballot for local representatives to the respondent and ask) If the elections for local representatives were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PRI); 0=Not Incumbent 128 (Desprender boleta para eleccion de Diputados Locales) Con esta boleta no oficial y que es 5610 para propositos de esta encuesta, digame por favor, si hoy hubiera elecciones para diputados locales, gpor cual partido votaria usted? (Pida que deposite la boleta en la urna) Gubernatorial Approval [In general, do you approve or disapprove of the way Patricio Martinez is doing his job as govemor?] 1. Approves completely 2. Approves some 3. Disapproves some 4. Disapproves completely 5. Don’t know/Did not answer Recode: 1=Disapproves completely; 2=Approves/Disapproves some; 3=Approves completely En general, busted aprueba o desaprueba Ia forma en que Patricio Martinez esta haciendo su trabajo como Gobemador? (Insistir: lo...totalmente o algo?) I. Aprueba totalmente 2. Aprueba a1 go 3. Desaprueba algo 4. Desaprueba totalmente 5. No sabe/No contesto State Economy [In general, do you consider conditions in Chihuahua have improved, remained the same or worsened under the administration of Patricio Martinez?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2 + 4=Same, 3=Improved En general, gusted considera que la situacién de Chihuahua ha mejorado, sigue igual 0 ha empeorado con el trabajo de Patricio Martinez como Gobemador? (Insistir: ...totalmente o algo?) 1. Mejorado totalmente 2. Mejorado algo 3. Sigue igual 4. Empeorado algo 5. Empeorado totalmente 6. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances [How do you rate your own economic conditions compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same I29 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2 + 4=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacion economica personal mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Party ID [In general, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?] 1. Very priista 2. Somewhat priista 3. Very panista 4. Somewhat panista 5. Very perredista 6. Somewhat perredista 7. Other 8. None Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PRI) [includes “very priista” and “somewhat priista”], 0=Not Incumbent Generalmente, gusted se considera priista, panista o perredista? 1. Muy priista 2. Algo priista 3. Muy panista 4. Algo panista 5. Muy perredista 6. Algo perredista 7. Otro 8. Ninguno 9. No sabe/No contesto Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial elections taking place in the state?] 1. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2 + 3 + 5)=Some; 3=A lot 130 gQué tan interesado esta usted en las campafias de los candidatos a la Gubernatura del Estado? 1. Mucho 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada 5. No sabe/No contesto Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubernatorial elections will take place in the state?] 1. Mentioned exact date 2. Mentioned incomplete date 3. Does not remember 4. Does not know 5. Did not answer Recoded: 1=Does not know; 2 (2+3+5)=Incomplete; 3=Complete gSabe usted la fecha de las proximas elecciones para Gobemador de Chihuahua? 1. Sabe la fecha completa 2. Supo solo e1 mes y el afio 3. Supo solo el afio 4. No la sabe 5. No contesto Education gHasta que afio o grado aprobo (paso) en la escuela? l. Ninguno 2. Preescolar o Kinder 3. Primaria 4. Secundaria 5. Preparatoria o bachillerato 6. Normal 7. Carrera te’cnica o comercial 8. Profesional 9. Maestria o Doctorado 10. No sabe/No contesto Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University Income See Chiapas. Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Rura1; 3=Mixed] Recoded: 1=Urban/Mixed, 0=Rural I31 Tipo de localidad: l. Urbano 2. Rural 3. Mixto JALISCO Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent Le voy a entregar una boleta con Ios nombres de los candidatos parecida a la que se usara el dia de las elecciones. Esta boleta no es oficial y solo se utilizara para propésitos de esta encuesta. Por favor marque en ella, si hoy hubiera elecciones para Gobemador de J alisco, gpor quién votaria usted? Solicitar que la boleta se deposite en la uma. Vote Choice, Local Legislature [(Hand out ballot containing ballot for local representatives to the respondent and ask) If the elections for local representatives were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent (Entregar boleta con partidos y preguntar: Si hoy hubiera elecciones para diputados locales, gpor cual partido votaria usted? (Pedir que deposite la boleta en la uma) Gubernatorial Approval [In general, do you approve or disapprove of the way Alberto Cardenas is doing his job as govemor?] 1. Approves completely 2. Approves some 3. Disapproves some 4. Disapproves completely 5. Don’t know/Did not answer En general, gusted aprueba o desaprueba 1a forma como Alberto Cardenas esta haciendo su trabajo como Gobemador? (Insistir: lo...totalmente o algo?) 1. Aprueba totalmente 2. Aprueba algo 3. Desaprueba a1 go 4. Desaprueba totalmente 5. No sabe/No contesto 132 State Economy [In general, do you consider conditions in Jalisco have improved, remained the same or worsened under the administration of Alberto Cardenas?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved En general, gusted considera que el Gobiemo de Alberto Cardenas ha sido un buen Gobiemo 0 un mal Gobiemo? I. Buen Gobiemo 2. Mal Gobiemo 3. Ni bueno ni malo 4. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances This question was not asked in Jalisco. Party ID [In general, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?] 1. Very priista 2. Somewhat priista 3. Very panista 4. Somewhat panista 5. Very perredista 6. Somewhat perredista 7. Other 8. None Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PAN) [includes “very panista” and “somewhat panista”], 0=Not Incumbent Independientemente del partido por el que usted votaria, gcon cual partido politico se identifica mas?...Muy o algo? 1. Muy priista 2. Algo priista 3. Muy panista 4. Algo panista 5. Muy perredista 6. Algo perredista 7. Menciono otro 8. No sabe/No contesto 9. Ninguno 133 Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial elections taking place in the state?] 1. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2+3+5)=Some; 3=A lot gQué tan interesado esta usted en las campafias de los aspirantes al gobiemo de Jalisco: muy, algo, poco o nada interesado? 1. Muy 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada 5. No sabe/No contesto Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubernatorial elections will take place in the state?] I. Mentioned exact date 2. Mentioned incomplete date 3. Does not remember 4. Does not remember/Does not know Recoded: I (3+4)=Does not know; 2=Incomplete; 3=Complete gMe podria decir la fecha en que se llevaran a cabo las pro'ximas elecciones para Gobemador de J alisco. . .0 en este momento no recuerda? 1. Menciono fecha completa 2. Menciono fecha incompleta 3. No recuerda/No sabe Education gHasta que afio o grado aprobo (paso) en la escuela? . Ninguno . Preescolar o Kinder . Primaria incompleta . Primaria completa . Secundaria incompleta . Secundaria completa . Preparatoria o bachillerato incompleto . Preparatoria o bachillerato completo . Carrera técnica o comercial 10. Normal 11. Universidad incompleta OWQO‘M-RUJNI—t I34 12. Universidad completa 13. Maestria o Doctorado incompleto 14. Maestn’a o Doctorado complete 15. No sabe/No contesto Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University Income See Chiapas. Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Mixed; 3=Rural] Recoded: 1=Urban/Mixed, 0=Rural Tipo de localidad: 1. Urbano 2. Mixto 3. Rural MICHOACAN Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PRD); 0=Not Incumbent (Entregar boleta con candidatos a1 entrevistado y preguntar): Le voy a entregar una boleta con los nombres de los candidatos a Gobemador. Si hoy hubiera elecciones para Gobemador del estado, por quien votaria usted? (Pedir que marque su voto en la boleta y solicitar que esta se deposite en la uma) Vote Choice, Local Legislature (Entregar boleta para Diputados Locales al entrevistado y preguntar): Le voy a entregar otra boleta. Si hoy hubiera elecciones para diputados locales, (3pm cual partido votaria usted? (Pedir que marque su voto en la boleta y solicitar que esta se deposite en la urna) Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PRD); 0=Not Incumbent [(Hand out ballot containing ballot for local representatives to the respondent and ask) If the elections for local representatives were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Gubernatorial Approval [In general, do you approve or disapprove of the way Victor Manuel Tinoco Rubi is performing his job as govemor?] l. Approves completely I35 2. Approves some 3. Disapproves some 4. Disapproves completely 5. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Disapproves completely, 2=Approves/Disapproves some, 3=Approves completely En general, gusted aprueba o desaprueba la forma como Victor Manuel Tinoco Rubi esta haciendo su trabajo como gobemador del estado? (Insistir): lo (aprueba/desaprueba) totalmente o algo? 1. Aprueba totalmente 2. Aprueba algo 3. Desaprueba a1 go 4. Desaprueba totalmente 5. No sabe/No contesto State Economy [How do you rate economic conditions in the state compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que 1a situacion econémica del estado mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances [How do you rate your own economic conditions compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacion personal mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto I36 Party ID [In general, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?] . Very priista . Somewhat . Very panista . Somewhat panista . Very perredista . Somewhat perredista . Other . None 9. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PRD) [includes “very perredista” and “somewhat perredista”], 0=Not Incumbent OO\10\M-BUJNt—‘ Generalmente, gusted se considera priista, panista o perredista? . Muy priista . Algo priista . Muy panista . Algo panista . Muy perredista . Algo perredista . Otro . Ninguno 9. No sabe/No contesto OOQONUI-bDJNt-d Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial elections taking place in the state?] 1. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2+3+5)=Some; 3=A lot (,Que' tan interesado esta usted en las campafias de los candidatos a la gubematura del estado? 1. Mucho 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada 5. No sabe/No contesto Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubematurial elections will take place in the state?] 137 1. Mentioned exact date 2. Mentioned incomplete date 3. Does not remember Recoded: 1=Does not know; 2=Incomplete; 3=Complete gMe podria decir la fecha en que se llevaran a cabo las elecciones para Gobemador del estado. . .0 en este momento no recuerda? 1. Menciono fecha completa 2. Menciono fecha incompleta 3. No recuerda Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Rural] Tipo de localidad: 1. Urbano 2. Rural Education [What is the highest level of education you have completed?] 1=No formal schooling . 2. Primary schooling 3. Secondary/technical schooling 4. High school/equivalent 5. University and more 6. Did not answer Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University gHasta que afio estudio usted? gCual es su ultimo grado de estudios? 1. No tiene estudios 2. Primaria 3. Secundaria/Te’cnica 4. Preparatoria/Equivalente 5. Universidad o mas 6. No contesto Income See Chiapas. NUEVO LEON Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent I38 (Desprender boleta con candidatos a gobemador). Con esta boleta no oficial y que solo es para propésitos de esta encuesta, digame por favor, si las elecciones para Gobemador de Nuevo Leon fueran hoy, gpor cual candidato votaria usted? (Solicitar que la boleta se deposite en la urna). Vote Choice, Local Legislature [(Hand out ballot containing ballot for local representatives to the respondent and ask) If the elections for local representatives were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent Con esta boleta no oficial y que es solo para propositos de esta encuesta digame por favor, si las elecciones para diputados locales fueran hoy, gpor cual partido votaria usted? (Que deposite en la urna) Gubernatorial Approval [In general, do you approve or disapprove of the way Fernando Elizondo Barragan is performing his job as govemor?] 1. Approves completely 2. Approves some 3. Disapproves some 4. Disapproves completely 5. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Disapproves completely, 2=Approves/Disapproves some, 3=Approves completely En general, gusted aprueba o desaprueba la forma como Fernando Elizondo Barragan esta haciendo su trabajo como Gobemador? (Insistir): lo (aprueba/desaprueba) totalmente o algo? 1. Aprueba totalmente 2. Aprueba algo 3. Desaprueba algo 4. Desaprueba totalmente 5. No sabe/No contesto State Economy [How do you rate economic conditions in the state compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved En general, gUsted considera que la situacion de Nuevo Leon ha mejorado, sigue igual 0 ha empeorado con el trabajo de Fernando Elizondo como Gobemador? 139 1. Mejorado totalmente 2. Mejorado algo 3. Sigue igual 4. Empeorado algo 5. Empeorado totalmente 6. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances [How do you rate your own economic conditions compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacion personal mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Party ID [In general, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?] 1. Very priista 2. Somewhat 3. Very panista 4. Somewhat panista 5. Very perredista 6. Somewhat perredista 7. Other 8. None 9. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PAN) [includes “very panista” and “somewhat panista”], 0=Not Incumbent Generalmente, gusted se considera priista, panista o perredista?...muy o algo? 1. Muy priista 2. Algo priista 3. Muy panista 4. Algo panista 5. Otro 6. Ninguno 7. No sabe/No contesto 140 Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial elections taking place in the state?] 1. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2+3+5)=Some; 3=A lot gQué tan interesado esta usted en votar en las elecciones de Gobemador de Nuevo Leon de este afio? 1. Mucho 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada 5. No sabe/No contesto Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubematurial elections will take place in the state?] 1. Knows exact date 2. Knows only the year 3. Knows only the month and year 4. Does not know 5. Did not answer Recoded: 1 (3+4+5)=Does not know; 2 (2+3)=Incomplete; 3=Complete éSabe usted la fecha de las proximas elecciones para Gobemador de Nuevo Leon? 1. Sabe la fecha completa 2. Supo solo el afio 3. Supo solo el mes y el afio 4. No la sabe 5. No contesto Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Rural] Tipo de localidad: 1. Urbano 2. Rural Education [What is the highest level of education you have completed?] 1=No formal schooling 2. Primary schooling 141 3. Secondary/technical schooling 4. High school/equivalent 5. University and more 6. Did not answer Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University gHasta que afio estudio usted? gCual es su ultimo grado de estudios? 1. Ninguno 2. Preescolar o Zinder 3. Primaria 4. Secundaria 5. Preparatoria o bachillerato 6. Normal 7. Carrera te’cnica o comercial 8. Profesional 9. Maestria o Doctorado 99. No sabe/No contesto Income See Chiapas. QUERETARO Vote Choice, Gubernatorial Elections [(Hand out ballot containing candidates’ names to the respondent and ask) If the elections for governor were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent (Entregar boleta con candidatos a1 entrevistado y preguntar): Le voy a entregar una boleta con los nombres de los candidatos a Gobemador. Si hoy hubiera elecciones para Gobemador del estado, gpor quién votaria usted? (Pedir que marque su voto en la boleta y solicitar que esta se deposite en la urna) Vote Choice, Local Legislature [(Hand out ballot containing ballot for local representatives to the respondent and ask) If the elections for local representatives were taking place today, for whom would you vote? (Ask respondent to place ballot in the ballot box)] Recoded: 1=Incumbent Party (PAN); 0=Not Incumbent Entregar boleta para Diputados Locales al entrevistado y preguntar): Le voy a entregar otra boleta. Si hoy hubiera elecciones para diputados locales, gpor cual partido votaria usted? (Pedir que marque su voto en la boleta y solicitar que esta se deposite en la uma) 142 Gubernatorial Elections [In general, do you approve or disapprove of the way Ignacio Loyola Vera is performing his job as govemor?] 1. Approves completely 2. Approves some 3. Disapproves some 4. Disapproves completely 5. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Disapproves completely, 2=Approves/Disapproves some, 3=Approves completely En general, gusted aprueba o desaprueba la forma como Ignacio Loyola Vera esta haciendo su trabajo como gobemador del estado? (Insistir): Io (aprueba/desaprueba) totalmente o algo? 1. Aprueba totalmente 2. Aprueba algo 3. Desaprueba algo 4. Desaprueba totalmente 5. No sabe/No contesto . State Economy , [How do you rate economic conditions in the state compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacion economica del estado mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Personal Finances [How do you rate your own economic conditions compared to a year ago?] 1. Improved 2. Same 3. Worsened 4. Don’t know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Worsened, 2=Same, 3=Improved Comparada con hace un afio, gdiria usted que su situacion personal mejoro, empeoro, o sigue igual? 1. Mejoro 143 2. Sigue igual 3. Empeoro 4. No sabe/No contesto Party [D [In general, do you consider yourself priista, panista, or perredista?] 1. Very priista 2. Somewhat priista 3. Very panista 4. Somewhat panista 5. Very perredista 6. Somewhat perredista 7. Other 8. None Recoded: 1=Incumbent (PAN) [includes “very panista” and“somewhat panista”], O=Not Incumbent Generalmente, gusted se considera priista, panista o perredista? 1. Muy priista 2. Algo priista 3. Muy panista 4. Algo panista 5. Muy perredista 6. Algo perredista 7. Otro 8. Ninguno 9. No sabe/No contesto Interest [How interested are you in the political campaigns going on related to the gubernatorial . elections taking place in the state?] I. A lot 2. Some 3. A little 4. Not at all 5. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1=Nothing; 2 (2+3+5)=Some; 3=A lot LQué tan interesado esta usted en las campafias de los candidatos a la gubematura del estado: mucho, algo, poco o nada interesado? 1. Mucho 2. Algo 3. Poco 4. Nada 5. No sabe/No contesto 144 Knowledge [Can you tell me the date when the next gubernatorial elections will take place in the state?] 1. Mentioned exact date 2. Mentioned incomplete date 3. Does not remember 4. Does not know/Did not answer Recoded: 1 (3+4)=Does not know; 2=Incomplete; 3=Complete gMe podria decir la fecha en que se llevaran a cabo las elecciones para Gobemador del estado. . .0 en este momento no recuerda? 1. Menciono fecha completa 2. Menciono fecha incompleta 3. No recuerda 4. No sabe/No contesto Locality [Type of locality: 1=Urban; 2=Rural] Tipo de localidad: 1. Urbano 2. Rural Education [What is the highest level of education you have completed?] 1=No formal schooling 2. Primary schooling 3. Secondary/technical schooling 4. High school/equivalent 5. University and more 6. Did not answer Recoded: 1=Secondary or less, 2=Preparatory; 3=University gHasta que afio estudio usted? gCual es su ultimo grado de estudios? 1. No tiene estudios 2. Primaria 3. Secundaria/Técnica 4. Preparatoria/Equivalente 5. Universidad o mas 6. No contesté Income See Chiapas. 145 Appendix C. List of States AGS BC BCS CAMP COAH COL CHIS CHIH DF DGO GTO GRO HGO JAL MEX MICH MOR NAY NL OAX PUE QRO QROO SLP SIN SON TAB TAM TLAX VER YUC ZAC State Aguascalientes Baja California Baja California Sur Campeche Coahuila Colima Chiapas Chihuahua Distrito Federal Durango Guanajuato Guerrero Hidalgo Jalisco México Michoacan Morelos Nayarit Nuevo Leon Oaxaca Puebla Querétaro Quintana Roo San Luis Potosi Sinaloa Sonora Tabasco Tamaulipas Tlaxcala Veracruz Yucatan Zacatecas 146 BIBLIOGRAPHY Almond, Gabriel A. and Sidney Verba. 1963. The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Alt, James E. and Robert C. Lowry. 1994. “Divided Government, Fiscal Institutions, and Budget Deficits: Evidence from the States.” American Political Science Review 88(4):811-828. Alt, James E., David Dreyer Lassen, and David Skilling. 2002. “Fiscal Transparency, Gubernatorial Approval, and the Scale of Government: Evidence from the States.” State Politics and Policy Quarterly 2(3):230-250. Ames, Barry. 1987. Political Survival: Politicians and Public Policy in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Ames, Barry. 1970. “Bases de apoyo del partido dominante en México.” F oro Internacional l l(1):50-76. Anderson, Christopher J. 2000. “Economic Voting and Political Context: A Comparative Perspective.” Electoral Studies 19:151-170. Anderson, Leslie E. and Lawrence C. Dodd. 2005. Learning Democracy: Citizen Engagement and Electoral Choice in Nicaragua, 1990-2001. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Arellano Cadena, Rogelio (ed). 1996. Mexico Hacia un Nuevo F ederalismo Fiscal. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Economica. Atkeson, Lonna Rae and Randall W. Partin. 1995. “Economic and Referendum Voting: A Comparison of Gubernatorial and Senatorial and Senatorial Elections.” American Political Science Review 89(1):99-107. Aziz Nassif, Alberto. 2000. Los ciclos de la democracia: Gobiemo y elecciones en Chihuahua. Mexico City: Miguel Angel Porrua. Aziz Nassif, Alberto. 1994. Chihuahua: Historial de una Alternativa. Mexico City: La Jornada/CIESAS. Bahl, Roy and Johannes Linn. 1986. “Public Expenditure Decentralization in Developing Countries.” Government Policy 4:405-418. Bailey, John. 1994. “Centralism and Political Change in Mexico: The Case of National Solidarity,” in Cornelius, Wayne A., Ann L. Craig, and Jonathan Fox (eds.). Transforming State-Society Relations in Mexico: The National Solidarity Strategy. La Jolla, CA: Center for US-Mexican Studies, UCSD. I47 Becerra, Ricardo, Pedro Salazar, and Jose’ Woldenberg. 2000. La mecdnica del cambio politico en México: Elecciones, partidos y reformas. Mexico City: Ediciones Cal y Arena. Beer, Caroline C. 2003. Electoral Competition and Institutional Change in Mexico. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Beer, Caroline C. 2004. “Electoral Competition and Fiscal Decentralization in Mexico,” in Alfred P. Montero and David J. Samuels (eds.). Decentralization and Democracy in Latin America. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Besley, Timothy and Anne Case. 1995. “Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1 10(3):769-798. Bickers, Kenneth and Robert M. Stein. 1996. “The Electoral Dynamics of the Federal Pork Barrel.” American Journal of Political Science 40(4): 1300-1326. Bird, Richard M. and Francois Vaillancourt. 1998. Fiscal Decentralization in Developing Countries. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Bratton, Michael. 1998. “Second Elections in Africa.” Journal of Democracy 9(3):51-66. Bratton, Michael, Robert Mattes, and E. Gyimah-Boadi. 2005. Public Opinion, Democracy, and Market Reform in Afiica. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Bratton, Michael and Nicholas van de Walle. 1997. Democratic Experiments in Afiica: Regime Transitions in Comparative Perspective. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Bruhn, Kathleen. 1997. Taking on Goliath: The Emergence of a New Left and the Struggle for Democracy in Mexico. University Park, PN: The Pennsylvania State University Press. Buendia Laredo, Jorge. 1996. “Economic Reform, Public Opinion and Presidencial Approval in Mexico, 1988-1993.” Comparative Political Studies 29:566-592. Cabrero, Enrique. 1995. La nueva gestion municipal en México: Andlisis de experiencias innovadoras en gobiernos locales. Mexico City: Miguel Angel Porrua/CIDE. Camp, Roderic Ai. 2003. Politics in Mexico. The Democratic Transformation. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Camp, Roderic Ai. 1996. Politics in Mexico. Second Edition. New York, NY: Oxford 148 University Press. Camp, Roderic Ai. 1993. Politics in Mexico. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Camp, Roderic Ai. 1980. Mexico’s Leaders: Their Education and Recruitment. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. Carsey, Thomas M. and Gerald C. Wright. 1998. “State and National Factors in Gubernatorial and Senatorial Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 42(3):994-1002. Centro de Investigacion Para e1 Desarrollo, A. C. (CIDAC). 2005. Base de datos de elecciones locales, 1980-2005. http://www.cidac.org Chand, Vikram Khub. 2001. Mexico’s Political Awakening. Notre Dame, IN: Notre Dame University Press. Chappell, Henry W. Jr. and William R. Keech. 1985. “A New View of Political Accountability for Economic Performance.” American Political Science Review 79:10-27. Chubb John E. 1985. “The Political Economy of Federalism.” American Political Science Review 79(4):994-1015. Chubb, John E. 1988. “Institutions, the Economy, and the Dynamics of State Elections.” American Political Science Review 82(1):81-154. Clarke, Harold D. and Marianne C. Stewart. 1994. “Prospections, Retrospections, and Rationality: The ‘Bankers’ Model of Presidential Approval Reconsidered.” American Journal of Political Science 38(4):] 104-1 123. Coleman, Kenneth M. 1975. “The capital city electorate and Mexico’s Accion Nacional: Some survey evidence on conventional hypotheses.” Social Science Quarterly (56). Collier, David and Steven Levitsky. 1997. “Democracy with Adjectives: Conceptual Innovation in Comparative Research.” World Politics 49(3):430-451. Consejo Nacional de Poblacion (CONAPO). Proyecciones de poblacio'n a mitad de afio por sexo y entidadfederativa, 1970-2030. Cornelius, Wayne A. 1999. “Subnational Politics and Democratization: Tensions Between Center and Periphery in the Mexican Political System,” in Subnational Politics and Democratization in Mexico. Wayne A. Cornelius, Todd A. Eisenstadt, and J. Hindley (eds.). La Jolla, CA: Center for US-Mexican Studies, UCSD. I49 Cornelius, Wayne A. 1969. “Urbanization as an Agent in Latin American Political Instability: The case of Mexico.” American Political Science Review 63(3):833- 857. Cornelius, Wayne A., and Ann L. Craig. 1991. The Mexican Political System in Transition. Monograph Series 35. La Jolla, CA: Center for US-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Cornelius, Wayne A., Ann L. Craig, and Jonathan Fox (eds.). 1994. Transforming State- Society Relations: The National Solidarity Strategy. US-Mexico Contemporary Perspectives Series, 6. La Jolla, CA: Center for US-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Craig, Ann L. and Wayne Cornelius. 1995. “Houses Divided: Parties and Political Reform in Mexico,” in Scott Mainwaring and Timothy R. Scully (eds.). Building Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Dahl, Robert A. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Dennis, Jack. 1991. “The Study of Electoral Behavior,” in William Grattz (ed.). Political Science Looking to the Future. Political Behavior 3:51-89. Diamond, Larry. 1999. Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation. Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Diamond, Larry and Leonardo Morlino (eds.). 2005. Assessing the Quality of Democracy. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Diamond, Larry and Doh Chull Shin. 2000. “Introduction: Institutional Reform and Democratic Consolidation in Korea,” in Larry Diamond and Doh Chull Shin (eds.). Institutional Reform and Democratic Consolidation in Korea. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press. Diamond, Larry, Marc F. Plattner, and Andreas Schedler. 1999. “Introduction,” in Andreas Schedler, Larry Diamond, and Marc F. Plattner (eds.). The Self- Restraining State: Power and Accountability in New Democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Diamond, Larry, Jonathan Hartlyn, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour Martin Lipset. 1999. “Introduction: Politics, Society, and Democracy in Latin America,” in Larry Diamond, Jonathan Hartlyn, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour Martin Lipset. Democracy in Developing Countries: Latin America. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Diamond, Larry and Marc F. Plattner (eds.). 1994. Nationalism, Ethnic Conflict, and 150 Democracy. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Diaz-Cayeros, Alberto. 1995. Desarrollo Econémico e Inequidad Regional: Hacia un Nuevo Pacto Federal en Me'xico. Mexico City: F undacién Friedrich Naumann en México, Centro de Investigacion para el Desarrollo, A.C., and Miguel Angel Porrua. Dominguez, Jorge I. and Chappell Lawson (eds.). 2004. Mexico 's Pivotal Democratic Election. Candidates, Voters, and The Presidential Campaign of 2000. Stanford and La Jolla, CA: Stanford University Press and Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Dominguez, Jorge I. and Alejandro Poiré. 1999. Toward Mexico’s Democratization. New York, NY and London: Routledge. Dominguez, Jorge I. and James A. McCann. 1996. Democratizing Mexico. Public Opinion and Electoral Choices. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press. Dominguez, Jorge I. and James A. McCann. 1995. “Shaping Mexico’s Electoral Arena: The Construction of Partisan Cleavages in the 1988 and 1991 National Elections.” American Political Science Review 89(1):34-48. Dorussen, Han and Harvey D. Palmer. 2002. “The Context of Economic Voting: An Introduction,” in Dorussen, Han and Michaell Taylor. Economic Voting. New York, NY: Routledge/ECPR Studies in European Political Science. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York, NY: Harper & Brothers. Duch, Raymond M. 2001. “A Developmental Model of Heterogeneous Economic Voting in New Democracies.” American Political Science Review 95(4):895-910. Easton, David. 1965. A Systems Analysis of Political Life. New York, NY: John Wiley. Escobar-Lemmon, Maria. 2003. “Political Support for Decentralization: An Analysis of l the Colombian and Venezuelan Legislatures.” American Journal of Political ‘ Science 47(4):683-697. Eisenstadt, Todd. 2004. Courting Democracy in Mexico. Party Strategies and Electoral Institutions. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Erickson, RS. 1989. “Economic Conditions and the Presidential Vote.” American Political Science Review 83(2): 567-573. Espinoza Valle, Victor Alejandro. 1999. “Altemation and Political Liberalization: The 151 PAN in Baja California,” in Cornelius, Wayne A., Todd A. Eisenstadt and Jane Hindley (eds.). Subnational Politics and Democratization in Mexico. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Fagen, Richard R., and William S. Tuohy. 1972. Politics and Privilege in a Mexican City. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. F iorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Fiorina, Morris P. 1978. “Economic Retrospective Voting in American National Elections: A Micro-Level Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 22:246-243. Fox, Jonathan. 1994. “The Difficult Transition from Clientelism to Citizenship: Lessons from Mexico.” World Politics 46(2): 151-184. Furtak, Robert K. 1969. “El Partido Revolucionario Institucional: integracion nacional y movilizacion electoral.” F oro Internacional 9(2):339-352. Garman, Christopher, Stephan Haggard, and Eliza Willis. 2001. “Fiscal Decentralization: A Political Theory with Latin American Cases.” World Politics 53:205-236. Garrido, Luis Javier. 1989. “The Crisis of Presidentialism,” in Wayne Cornelius, Judith Gentleman, and Peter Smith (eds.). Mexico’s Alternative Political Futures. La Jolla, CA: Center for US-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Ge’lineau, Francois. 2002. “Economic Voting in Volatile Contexts: National and Subnational Politics in Latin America.” Ph.D. diss. University of New Mexico. Golden, David G. and James M. Poterba. 1980. “The Price of Popularity: The Political Business Cycle Reexamined.” American Journal of Political Science 24(4):696- 714. Gomez, Brad T. and J. Matthew Wilson. 2006. “Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: A Comparative Analysis of Four Democratic Electorates.” American Journal of Political Science 50(1): 127-145. Gomez, Brad T. and J. Matthew Wilson. 2001. “Political Sophistication and Economic Voting in the American Electorate: A Theory of Heterogeneous Attribution.’ American Journal of Political Science 45(4):899-914. 9 Gomez-Tagle, Silvia. 1992. “Balance de las elecciones de 1991 en Mexico.” Revista Mexicana de Sociologia 54(1):253-287. Gomez-Tagle, Silvia. 1989. “La dificultad de perder: el partido oficial en la coyuntura de 152 1988.” Revista Mexicana de Sociologia 52(4): 239-260. Gonzalez Casanova, Pablo. 1965. La Democracia en México. Mexico City: Era. Gonzalez Graf, Jaime (ed.). 1988. Las Elecciones de 1988 y la Crisis del Sistema Politico Mexicana. Mexico City: Instituto Mexicano de Estudios Politicos/Diana. Gyimah-Boadi, E. 1998. “The Rebirth of African Liberalism.” Journal of Democracy 9(2): 1 8-3 1. Haggard, Stephan and Steven Webb (eds.). 1994. Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment. New York, NY: Oxford University Press/World Bank. Hagopian, Frances. 1990. “Democracy by Undemocratic Means: Elites, Political Pacts, and Regime Transition in Brazil.” Comparative Political Studies 23: 147-170. Harper, Marcus A. G. 2000. “Economic Voting in Postcommunist Eastern Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 33(9): 1 191-1227. Hibbs, Douglas A., Jr., Douglas Rivers, and Nicholas Vasilatos. 1982. “On the Demand for Economic Outcomes: Macroeconomic Performance and Mass Political Support in the United States, Great Britain, and Germany.” The Journal of Politics 44:426-462. Hiskey, Jonathan. 2005. “The Political Economy of Subnational Economic Recovery in Mexico.” Latin American Research Review 40(1):30-55. Hiskey, Jonathan T. and Shaun Bowler. 2005. “Local Context and Democratization in Mexico.” American Journal of Political Science 49(1):57-71. Holbrook, Thomas M. and Emily Van Dunk. 1993. “Electoral Competition in the American States.” American Political Science Review, 87(4): 955-962. Holbrook-Provow, Thomas M. 1987. “National factors in gubernatorial elections.” American Politics Quarterly 15:471-483. Howell, Susan E., and J .M. Vanderleeuw. 1990. “Economic Effects on State Governors.” American Politics Quarterly 15:471-483. Huntington, Samuel. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press. Instituto Federal Electoral (IFE). Atlas Electoral Federal de México 1970-2003. Instituto Nacional de Estadistica, Geografia e Informatica, INEGI. F inanzas Pziblicas 153 Estatales y Municipales de México, 1970-2004 (various issues). Aguascalientes, Mexico: INEGI. http://www.inegi.gob.mx Instituto Nacional de Estadistica, Geografia e Inforrnatica, INEGI. 2001. XII Censo General de Poblacién y Vivienda. http://www.inegi.gob.mx Jones, Mark P. 1995. Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Jones, Mark P., Pablo Sanguinetti, and Mariano Tommassi. 1999. “Politics, Institutions, and Public-Sector Spending in the Argentina Provinces,” in Poterba, James M. and Jfirgen von Hagen (eds.). Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Karl, Terry Lynn. 1990. “Dilemmas of Democratization in Latin America.” Comparative Politics 22: 1-20. Kaufman, Clifford. 1972. “Urbanization, material satisfaction and mass political involvement: The poor in Mexico City.” Comparative Political Studies 4(3). Key, V.O. Jr. 1966. The Responsible Electorate, Rationality in Presidential Elections. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Key, V.O. Jr. 1964. Politics, Parties, and Pressure Groups. New York, NY: Thomas Y. Crowell. Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1981. “Policy-Oriented Voting in Response to Economic Issues.” American Political Science Review 75:448-459. Kinder, Donald R. and D. Roderick Kiewiet. 1978. “Economic Discontent and Political Behavior: The Role of Personal Grievances and Collective Economic Judgments in Congressional Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 23(3):495-527. Kinder, Donald R. and D. Roderick Kiewiet. 1981. “Sociotropic Politics: The American Case.” British Journal of Political Science 1 1:129-161. King, J .D. 2001. “Incumbent popularity and vote choice in gubernatorial elections.” Journal of Politics 63:585-597. Klesner, Joseph L. 1995. “The 1994 Mexican elections: manifestation of a divided society?” Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos l 1(1):137-149. Klesner, Joseph L. 1988. Electoral Reform in an Authoritarian Regime: The Case of Mexico. Ph.D. diss., Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Klorman, R. 1978. “Trend in Personal Finances and the Vote.” Public Opinion Quarterly 154 42:31-48. Kramer, Gerald H. 1971. “Short-Tenn Fluctuations in US. Voting Behavior, 1986- 1964.” The American Political Science Review 65: 131-143. Lawson, Chappell. 2002. Building the Fourth Estate: Democratization and the Rise of a Free Press in Mexico. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Levy, Daniel C. and Kathleen Bruhn, with Emilio Zebadua. 2001. Mexico. The Struggle for Democratic Development. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1988. Economics and Elections: The Major Western Democracies. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. and Mary Stegmaier. 2000. “Economic Determinants of Electoral Outcomes.” Annual Review of Political Science 3: 183-219. Lewis-Beck, Michael S. and Martin Paldam. 2000. “Economic Voting: An Introduction.” Electoral Studies 19:1 13-121. Linz, Juan J. 1990. “The Perils of Presidentialism.” Journal of Democracy 1(1):51-69. Linz, Juan J. and Alfred Stepan. 1996. Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Lowry, Robert C., James E. Alt, and Karen E. Ferree. 1998. “Fiscal Policy Outcomes and Electoral Accountability in American States.” American Political Science Review 92(4):759-774. Lujambio, Alonso. 2000. El Poder Compartido. Mexico City: Ed. Océano. MacKuen, Michael B., Robet S. Erikson, and James A. Stimson. 1989. “Macropartisanship.” American Political Science Review 83(4)21125-1142. MacKuen, Michael B., Robert S. Erikson, and James S. Stimson. 1992. “Peasants or Bankers? The American Electorate and the US. Economy.” American Political Science Review 86(3):597-611. Magaloni, Beatriz. 1997. The Dynamics of Ruling Party Decline: The Mexican Transition to Multipartism. Ph.D. diss., Duke University. Magaloni, Beatriz. 1994. “Eleccion racional y voto estratégico: Algunas aplicaciones para el caso mexicano.” Politica y Gobiemo l(2):309-344. Mainwaring, Scott. 1999. Rethinking Party Systems in the Third Wave of 155 Democratization. The Case of Brazil. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. “Presidentialism, Multipartism, and Democracy: The Difficult Combination.” Comparative Political Studies 26(2):]198-1228. Manin, Bernard, Adam Przeworski, and Susan C. Stokes. 1999. “Elections and Representation,” in Adam Przeworski, Susan C. Stokes, and Bernard Manin (eds.). Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Markowski, Radoslaw, and Gabor Toka. 1998. “Left Turn in Poland and Hungary Five Years after the Collapse of Communism.” Sisyphus 1(9):75-99. Markus, Gregory B. 1988. “The Impact of Personal and National Economic Conditions on the Presidential Vote: A Pooled Cross-Sectional Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 32: 137-154. Martinez Assad, Carlos (ed.). 1992. La Sucesién Presidencial en México, 1928-1988. Mexico City: Nueva Imagen. Merino, Mauricio (ed.). 1994. En busca de la democracia municipal. La participacio'n ciudadana en el gobiemo local mexicano. Mexico City: El Colegio de México. Meyer, Lorenzo, and Hector Aguilar Camin. 1993. In the Shadow of the Mexican Revolution: Contemporary Mexican History, 1910-1989. Austin, TX: University of Texas Press. Meyer, Lorenzo. 1986. “Un tema afiejo siempre actual: El centro y las regiones en la historia mexicana,” in Blanca Torres (ed.). Descentralizacion y Democracia en México. Mexico City: El Colegio de Mexico. Middlebrook, Kevin. 1986. “Political Liberalization in an Authoritarian Regime: The Case of Mexico,” in Paul W. Drake and E. Silva (eds.). Elections and Democratization in Latin America, 1985-1985. La Jolla, CA: Center for US- Mexican Studies, UCSD. Middlebrook, Kevin J. (ed.). 2001. Party Politics and the Struggle for Democracy in Mexico. National and State-Level Analyses of the Partido Accion Nacional. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Mishler, William, and Richard Rose. 1996. “Trajectories of Fear and Hope: Support for Democracy in Post-Communist Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 28(4):553-581. Mizrahi, Yemile. 2003. From Martyrdom to Power: The Partido Accion Nacional in Mexico. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. 156 Mizrahi, Yemile. 1995. “Entrepreneurs in the Opposition: Modes of Political Participation in Chihuahua,” in Rodriguez, Victoria E. and Peter M. Ward. Opposition Government in Mexico. Alburqueque, NM: University of New Mexico Press. Molina, J osé. 2001. “The electoral effect of underdevelopment: government turnover and its causes in Latin-American, Caribbean and industrialized countries.” Electoral Studies 20:427-446. Molinar Horcasistas, Juan. 1986. “The Mexican electoral system: continuity by change,” in Paul W. Drake and Eduardo Silva (eds.). Elections and democratization in Latin America, [980-1985. La Jolla, CA: Center for Iberian and Latin American Studies, UCSD. Molinar Horcasitas, Juan, and Jeffrey Weldon. 1990. “Elecciones de 1988 en Mexico: crisis del autoritarismo.” Revista Mexicana de Sociologia 52(4):229-262. Monsivais, Carlos. 1992. “‘Just Over that Hill’: Notes on Centralism and Regional Cultures,” in Eric Van Young (ed.). Mexico ’s Regions: Comparative History and Development. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, UCSD. Montero, Alfred P. and David J. Samuels (eds.). 2004. Decentralization and Democracy in Latin America. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press. Moreno, Alejandro. 2003. El Votante Mexicana. Democracia, Actitudes Politicas y Conducta Electoral. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Econémica. Moreno, Alejandro. 1993. “Agosto de 1991: éPor qué se voto por el PRI?” Este Pat's. (Dec):26-28. Moreno, Alejandro and Keith Yanner. 1995. “Predictors of voter preferences in Mexico’s 1994 presidential elections.” Paper presented at the Latin American Studies Association Meeting, Washington, DC. Morgenstem, Scott and Elizabeth Zechmeister. 2001. “Better the Devil you know than the Saint you Don’t? Risk Propensity and Vote Choice in Mexico.” Journal of Politics 63(1):93-119. Muller, Edward N. and Mitchell A. Seligson. 1994. “Civic Culture and Democracy: The Question of Causal Relationships.” American Political Science Review 88(3):635- 652. Nadeau, Richard, Richard G. Niemi, and Antoine Yoshinaka. 2002. “A cross-national analysis of economic voting: taking account of the political context across time and nations.” Electoral Studies 21:403-423. 157 Nannestad, P. and M. Paldam. 1994. “The VP-Function: A Survey of the Literature on Vote and Popularity Functions after 25 Years.” Public Choice 79:213-245. Niemi, Richard G., Harold W. Stanley, and Ronald J. Vogel. 1995. “State Economies and State Taxes: Do Voters Hold Governors Accountable?” American Journal of Political Science 39(4):936-957. Nickson, R. Andrew. 1995. Local Government in Latin America. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Norpoth, Helmut. 1996. “Presidents and the Prospective Voter.” The Journal of Politics 58(3):776-792. Norpoth, Helmut. 1984. Economics, Politics and the Cycle of Presidential Popularity. Political Behavior 6:252-273. O’Donnell, Guillermo. 1994. “Delegative Democracy.” Journal of Democracy 5(1):55- 69. O’Donnell, Guillermo, Philippe C. Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead (eds.). 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule. Latin America. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Pacek, Alexander, and Benjamin Radcliff. 1995. “The Political Economy of Competitive Elections in the Developing World.” American Journal of Political Science 39(3):745-759. Pacheco, Guadalupe. 1986. El PR1 y los procesos electorales de 1961 a 1985. Mexico City: UAM-Xochimilco. Partin, R. 1995 “Economic Conditions and Gubernatorial Elections: Is the State Executive Held Accountable?” American Politics Quarterly 23:81-95. Peltzman, Sam. 1992. “Voters as Fiscal Conservatives.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2):327-361. Peltzman, Sam. 1990. “How Efficient is the Voting Market?” Journal of Law & Economics 33:27-63. Peltzman, Sam. 1987. “Economic Conditions and Gubernatorial Elections.” American Economic Review 77:293-297. Piereson, James E. 1975. “Presidential Popularity and Midterm Voting at Different Electoral Levels.” American Journal of Political Science 29(4):683-694. 158 Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persuasion in Presidential Campaigns. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Posner, Daniel N. and David J. Simon. 2002. “Economic Conditions and Incumbent Support in Africa’s New Democracies. Evidence from Zambia.” Comparative Political Studies 35(3):313-336. Poterba, James M. 1994. “State Responses to Fiscal Crises: The Effects of Budgetary Institutions and Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 102(4):799-821. Poterba, James M. and Jiirgen von Hagen (eds.). 1999. Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press. Powell, Bingham G., Jr. and Guy D. Whitten. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37(2):391-414. Prud’homme, Rémy. 1995. “The Dangers of Decentralization.” The World Bank Observer 10:201-220. Przeworski, Adam. 1996. “Public Support for Economic Reforms in Poland.” Comparative Political Studies 29:520-543. Przeworski, Adam, Stokes and Manin (eds.). 1999. Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Putnam, Robert D. with Robert Leonardi and Raffaella Y. Nanetti. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Quinn, Dennis P. And John T. Woolley. 2001. “Democracy and National Economic Performance: The Preference for Stability.” American Journal of Political Science 45(3):634-657. Ranney, Austin. 1976. “Parties in State Politics,” in Jacob, Herbert and Kenneth Vines (eds.). Politics in the American States. Boston, MA: Little Brown & Co. Remmer, Karen L. 1993. “The Political Economy of Elections in Latin America, 1980- 1991.” American Political Science Review 87(2):393-407. Remmer, Karen L. 1991. “The Political Impact of Economic Crisis in Latin America.” American Political Science Review 85:777-800. Remmer, Karen L. And Erik Wibbels. 2000. “The Subnational Politics of Economic Adjustment. Provincial Politics and Fiscal Performance in Argentina.” Comparative Political Studies 33(4):419-45 1 . 159 Remmer, Karen L. and Francois Gélineau. 2003. “Subnational Electoral Choice. Economic and Referendum Voting in Argentina, 1983-1999.” Comparative Political Studies 36(7):801-821 . Rezk, Ernesto. 1998. “Argentina: Fiscal Federalism and Decentralization,” in Richard M. Bird and Francois Vaillancourt (eds.). Fiscal Decentralization in Developing Countries. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Roberts, Bryan. 1992. “The Place of Regions in Mexico,” in Eric Van Young (ed.). Mexico ’s Regions: Comparative History and Development. La Jolla, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexican Studies, University of California, San Diego. Roberts, Kenneth M. and Eric Wibbels. 1999. “Party Systems and Electoral Volatility in Latin America: A Test of Economic, Institucional, and Structural Explanations.” American Political Science Review 93(3):575-590. Rodden, Jonathan and Eric Wibbels. 2002. “Beyond the Fiction of Federalism. Macroeconomic Management in Multitiered Systems.” World Politics 54:494- 531. Rodriguez, Victoria. 1997. Decentralization in Mexico: From Reforma Municipal to Solidaridad to Nuevo F ederalismo. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Rodriguez, Victoria E. and Peter Ward . 1996. New Federalism, State and Local Government in Mexico. Austin, TX: Mexican Center of the Institute of Latin American Studies, University of Texas at Austin. Rodriguez, Victoria E. and Peter Ward (eds.) 1995. Opposition Government in Mexico. Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico. Rodriguez, Victoria E. and Peter Ward. 1994. “Disentangling the PRI from the Government in Mexico.” Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos 10(1): 163-186. Rondinelli, Dennis. 1989. “Decentralizing Public Services in Developing Countries: Issues and Opportunities.” Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies 14(1):77-98. Rondinelli, Dennis. 1981. “Government Decentralization in Comparative Perspective.” International Review of Administrative Sciences 2: 133-145. Rose, Richard, William Mishler, and Christian Haerpher. 1998. Democracy and its Alternatives: Understanding Post-Communist Societies. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Rowland, Allison M. 2001. “Population as a Determinant of Local Outcomes under 160 Decentralization: Illustrations from Small Municipalities in Bolivia and Mexico.” World Development 29(8): 1373-1389. Samuels, David. 2003. “Presidents, Assemblies, and Accountability.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia. Sartori, Giovanni. 1970. “Concept Misforrnation in Comparative Politics,” American Political Science Review 64(4): 1033-1053. Schattschneider, Elmer Eric. 1942. Party Government. New York, NY: Farrar and Rinehart. Schedler, Andreas. 1999. “Conceptualizing Accountability,” in Andreas Schedler, Larry Diamond, and Marc F. Plattner (eds.). The Self-Restraining State: Power and Accountability in New Democracies. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Schmitter, Philippe C. and Terry Lynn Karl. 1991. “What Democracy Is. . .and Is Not.” Journal of Democracy 2(3):78- Schmitter, Philippe C. 2004. “The Ambiguous Virtues of Accountability.” Journal of Democracy 15(4):47-60. Schmitter, Philippe. 1997. “Civil Society East and West,” in Larry Diamond, Marc F. Plattner, Yun-han Chu, and Hung-mao Tien (eds.). Consolidating the Third Wave Democracies: Themes and Perspectives. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Segovia, Rafael. 1975. La Politizacién del Nifio Mexicana. Mexico City: El Colegio de México, Coleccién Centro de Estudios Internacionales (l4). Seong, Kyoung-Ryung. 2000. “Delayed Decentralization and Incomplete Democratic Consolidation,” in Larry Diamond and Doh Chull Shin (eds.). Institutional Reform and Democratic Consolidation in Korea. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press. Shugart, Matthew Soberg and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Simon, Dennis M. 1989. “Presidents, Governors, and Electoral Accountability.” Journal of Politics 51:286-304. Simon, Dennis M., Charles W. Ostrom, and Robin F. Marra. 1991. “The President, Referendum Voting, and Subnational Elections in the United States.” American Political Science Review 85:1 177-1 192. 161 Smith, Peter. 1979. Labyrinths of Power: Political Recruitment in Twentieth Century Mexico. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Solt, Frederick. 2004. “Electoral Competition, Legislative Pluralism, and Institutional Development: Evidence from Mexico’s States.” Latin American Research Review 39(1):]55-167. Solt, Frederick. 2003. “Explaining the Quality of New Democracies: Actors, Institutions, and Socioeconomic Structure in Mexico’s States.” Ph.D. diss. University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. Stein, Robert M. 1990. “Economic Voting for Governor and US. Senator: The Electoral Consequences of Federalism.” Journal of Politics 52(1):29-53. Stepan, Alfred. 2000. “Brazil’s Decentralize Federalism: Bringing Government Closer to the Citizens?” Daedalus 129(2): 145-169. Svoboda, Craig J. 1995. “Retrospective Voting in Gubernatorial Elections: 1982 and 1986.” Political Research Quarterly 48: 135-150. Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64:416-424. ' Tomasen, Jacques and Hermann Schmitt. 1997. “Policy Representation.” European Journal of Political Research 32:165-184. Tufte, Edward R. 1978. Political Control of the Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. United Nations Development Program. 1993. “People and Governance,” in Human Development. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Vargas Llosa, Mario. 2000. “De la Dictadura Perfecta a una Democracia Dificil.” Reforma. July 3:IIA. Ward, Peter M. 1993. “Social Welfare Policy and Political Opening in Mexico.” Journal of Latin American Studies 25:613-628. Ward, Peter M. 1995. “Policy Making and Policy Implementation Among Non-PRI Governments: The PAN in Ciudad Juarez and in Chihuahua,” in Peter M. Ward and Victoria E. Rodriguez (eds.). Opposition Government in Mexico. Alburqueque: University of New Mexico Press. Ward, Peter M. and Victoria E. Rodriguez. 1999. “New Federalism, Intra-govemmental Relations and Co-govemance in Mexico.” Journal of Latin American Studies 31:673-710. 162 Weatherford, M. Stephen. 1987. “How Does Government Performance Influence Political Support?” Political Behavior 9(1):5-28. Weldon, Jeffrey A. 1997. “The Political Sources of Presidencialismo in Mexico,” in Mainwaring, Scott and Matthew Shugart (eds.). Presidentialism in Latin America. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Weyland, Kurt. 2003. “Economic Voting Reconsidered. Crisis and Charisma in the Election of Hugo Chavez.” Comparative Political Studies 36(7):822-848. Wibbels, Erik. 2000. “Federalism and the Politics of Macroeconomic Policy and Performance.” American Journal of Political Science 44(4):687-702. Wilkin, Sam, Brandon Haller, and Helmut Norpoth. 1997. “From Argentina to Zambia: a World-Wide Test of Economic Voting.” Electoral Studies 16(3):301-316. Willis, Eliza, Christopher da CB, and Stephan Haggard. 1999. “The Politics of Decentralization in Latin America.” Latin American Research Review 34(1):7-56. Zavala, Ivan. 1991. “Factores sociales de la votacién por Carlos Salinas de Gortari.” Estudios Politicos 8:43-54. ‘ 163 GA uliltiltglltljlflltjlllwill?"