ENFEREOR {NPUTS AND EXIERNAL EFFECTS must: for the Dawn of DE. D. MECHIMN STATE UNIVERSITY Roger Blair 1968 TH can. 0-169 This is to certify that the thesis entitled INFERIOR INPUTS AND EXTERNAL EFFECTS presented by Roger Blair has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph 0 D . degree in ECODOmiCS <::::;ég;::7;/U 4:7[L_2 f“y*\,/// M4 jor pro essor Date May 8, 1968 ABSTRACT INFERIOR INPUTS AND EXTERNAL EFFECTS by Roger Blair This thesis explores the implications of inferior inputs on the solutions to the resource misallocation prob- lem created by external effects. To this end, the concepts of external effects and inferior inputs are systematically developed in separate chapters. Then a situation is hypoth— esized in which an inferior input is the cause of an exter- nal diseconomy. The solutions for removal of the Pareto relevance of this external diseconomy are subsequently analyzed. This analysis reveals that the solutions are unaffected by the influence of input inferiority. INFERIOR INPUTS AND EXTERNAL EFFECTS BY \ Roger'Blair A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1968 Q;§/44# ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Many people have greatly assisted me in whatever educational achievement this dissertation represents. It would be unconscionable not to thank all my former teachers; however, some deserve special mention: Professors Michael De Prano and Josef Hadar for my original interest in eco— nomics and Professors Walter Adams, Robert Lanzillotti, and Victor Smith for sustaining this interest. In addition, Professors Anthony K00 and John Moroney read this disserta- tion and offered helpful suggestions. .Special appreciation must be expressed to Professor Charles E. Ferguson for his suggestion of the topic, assistance in research, and rapid reading of the preliminary drafts. But, above all, I must thank my mother, my late father, and my wife, all who have done without that I might spend most of my life in school. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter I 0 INTRODUCTION 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 II. THE CONCEPT OF EXTERNALITIES . . . . . . . . The Definition of Externality . . . . . . The Effect of an Externality . . . . . . . Solutions for the Externality Problem . . Bargaining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Taxes and Subsidies . . . . . . . . . Mergers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Cost Functions and Reciprocal Externalities . . . . . . . . . . . . . Unilateral Externalities . . . . . . . Mutual Externalities . . . . . . . . . Second-Order Conditions . . . . . . . . . III. THE CONCEPT OF INFERIOR INPUTS . . . . . . . A Basic Model of Input Demand . . . . . . Inferior Inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . An Alternate View of Inferior Inputs . . Inferior Inputs and the Level of Profit . Input Inferiority and Restrictions on the Production Function . . . . . . . . Input Inferiority and the Cross-Elasticity of Input Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . Inferior Inputs and Output and Substitution Effects . . . . . . . . . . IV. THE INFLUENCE OF INFERIOR INPUTS UPON EXTERNALITY SOLUTIONS . . . . . . . . . . The General Problem . . . . . . . . . . . Solutions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bargaining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Taxes and Subsidies . . . . . . . . . Mergers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii Page 18 20 22 27 31 33 34 37 43 48 49 52 55 56 57 61 62 68 69 71 72 78 81 82 85 94 LIST OF APPENDICES Appendix Page A. DERIVATION OF COST FUNCTIONS WITH EXTERNALITIES PRESENT . . . . . . . . . . . 85 B. AN ALTERNATIVE VIEW OF THE EXTERNALITY— CAUS ING INPU'r O O O O O O O O O C O O O O O 9 1 iv CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ,Although the early discussions of external effects were filled with errors, inconsistencies, and semantic difficulties, as with most theoretical concepts, a clearer picture finally emerged. In 1959, F. M. Batorl cleared away most of the rubble and summarized the theory that had been developed. Since that time, there has appeared a host of articles on the subject. Some of these have represented attempts to define externalities more)precisely. Some dis- cussed various solutions to the resource misallocation prob- lem caused by external effects, i.e., the achievement of Pareto optimality. Still others have introduced further complications into this resource misallocation problem. This dissertation will also introduce a further complication: the influence of inferior inputs. While the notion of an inferior good, i.e., one whose consumption decreases as an individual's income increases, is certainly not new, the analogous concept of an inferior input was not clearly defined until D. V. T. Bear's 1F. M. Bator, "Anatomy of Market Failure," Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXII (1959), 351-79. article2 appeared. There have been but two subsequent developments of this concept. While Charles Plott's contri- bution3 was not very explicit, that of C. E. Ferguson4 was. I shall combine this concept with that of external effects by hypothesizing a case where one firm's use of an inferior input causes another firm to suffer an external diseconomy. The solutions that will "correct" the external- ity problem, i.e., that make the attainment of Pareto opti- mality possible, will then be analyzed. The purpose of this analysis is to determine whether these solutions still apply in this special case. To accomplish this, I shall carefully develop the definition and effects of externalities along with their solutions in Chapter II. The concept of inferior inputs and some of their consequences will be developed in Chapter III. After these careful surveys we shall have all the tools at hand to complete the investigation. This will be done in the concluding Chapter IV. ”2D. V. T. Bear, "Inferior Inputs and the Theory of the Firm," Journal of Political Economy, LXXIII (1965), 287-89. 3Charles Plott, "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," Economica, XXXIII (1966), 84-87. 4C. E. Ferguson, "'Inferior Factors' and the Theories of Production and Input Demand," Economica, to appear May . 1968. CHAPTER II THE CONCEPT OF EXTERNALITIES l. The Definition of Externality Mathematically, welfare maximization involves the solution of a constrained extremum problem. Solving this problem by Lagrange methods yields a set of first-order optimality conditions that include the familiar Lagrange multipliers. These multipliers represent the costs of the constraints. Thus, as Davis and Whinston note,1 they also represent the implied costs of the constraints on technology and the market prices of factors and commodities. Under the usual assumptions concerning tastes, technology, and profit maximization, the equilibrium quantities of inputs and com- modities that result from pure competitors responding to these prices will satisfy the conditions for Pareto effi- ciency. In other words, pure competition will put society on its "bliss" frontier. If the competitively imputed incomes could be redistributed without cost in some lump-sum 1O. A. Davis anth. B. Whinston, "Welfare Economics and the Theory of Second Best," The Review of Economic Studies, XXXII (1965), p. 4. way to achieve the "correct" income distribution, the social welfare function could then be maximized. Achieving the "bliss" frontier can be thwarted by many real world phenomena: imperfect information, inertia, non-profit maximizing behavior, risk and uncertainty, etc. But these foils can be ignored in this discussion as "they have to do with the efficiency of 'real life' people in a nonstationary world of uncertainty, miscalculation, etc."2 This thesis is concerned with the phenomena that disrupt Pareto-efficient resource allocation under the assumptions of individual profit- and utility—maximization in a station- ary world. These phenomena are labeled externalities. The discussion of these externalities will be largely in partial equilibrium terms; therefore, it must be understood that the rest of the economy is, and remains, organized so that the Pareto optimum conditions are fulfilled. As will be empha- Isized later, this does not involve a second-best situation. As Bator pointed out,3 the modern formulation of externalities is embedded in the idea of direct interaction. This interaction is a result of nonindependence of some utility and/or production functions, i.e., the nonindepen- dence may be between producers, between consumers, or between 2F. M. Bator, "The Anatomy of Market Failure," ' Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXII (l958), p. 352. 3F. M. Bator, "Market Failure," p. 358. producers and consumers. Such nonindependence causes some Paretian costs and benefits to be omitted from the decen- tralized, private cost-revenue calculations. In other words, it causes social costs and social benefits to diverge. Although Bator gives an example of this nonindependence con- cept of externality, his verbal definition is not wholly satisfactory. Buchanan and Stubblebine,4 however, have developed a precise set of definitions formulated in utility terms. These have been transformed into productivity terms because this thesis is concerned with production. Assume that there are two firms, i and j, with the following twice differentiable production functions: . = G x. ,x. ,...,x. 1.1 Q3 (31 32 3n) ( ) and Qi = F(xil,xiz,...,xin,z) (1.2) where xjk and xik are the amounts of input k used by firms j and 1 respectively. We also assume that aG/dxjk > 0 over the range considered as is aF/axik where k = l,2,...,n. The element 2 is defined as z = 9(le). (1.3) , 4J. M. Buchanan and W. C. Stubblebine, "Externality," Economica, N.S. XXIX (1962), 371-384. The concepts developed in equations (1.1) through (1.12) are simply re-statements in productivity terms of their concepts. i.e., j's use of input le yields some output 2 that enters i's production function. To avoid confusion, I must make it quite clear that z is some accidental by-product or condi- tion that j creates. We must emphasize that 2 has no market price. It is not the sort of by-product which is commonly sold. To clarify this point, consider the classic case of air pollution caused by a factory's operation where z repre- sents the smoke emitted, g represents the burning process, and le represents the fuel. Thus equation (1.2) implies that the output of i is a function of the inputs under its control and an output of j that is directly related to j's use of input le. This condition constitutes the presence of an externality. Input le was chosen as the externality-causing input merely for expositional convenience. Moreover, i's production function could be written to include other inputs under j's control; but without loss of generality, we may direct our attention to the effects of the single input le. In addition, since it serves no useful purpose to consider mutual, or reciprocal, externalities when discussing defini- tions, we assumed that j's production includes only inputs under its own control. One further comment requires mention: as a matter of notation we let dF/dxik = aF(xil,xiz,...,xin,z)/ axik’ i.e., dF/Bxik is, in general, a function of all the xi's and z. The abbreviated form will be used throughout, but its precise meaning should not be forgotten. Since i has no control over the level of z = g(le), z enters i's production function parametrically. Thus, we assume that i attempts to maximize profits in the usual way, subject to given values of 2. Whether i's optimum output must be modified to account for various values of z is a question considered later. Assuming i and j maximize profits independently and the product and factor markets are competitive, the problems are to n Max Vi — Pi F(Xil'xi2”'°’xin’z) -k§l pk xik (1.4) and n 1 Max mj— Pj G(le,xj2,...,xjn) — kil pk-xjk ( .5) where w is profit, Pi and Pj are the prices of the products i and j produce, pk is the price of input k, and the xik and x. are the quantities of the inputs used. jk The first-order conditions for profit maximization are Pi'dF/dxik - pk = 0 1f xik > O (k = l,2,...,n) (1.6) and Pj'dG/dxjk - pk = 0 1f xjk > O. (k = l,2,...,n) (1.7) These are the usual Pareto conditions: in equilibrium the value of the marginal product of each input must equal its parametrically given market price. But i cannot take account of 2 because there is no price attached to it even though it enters i's production function. In all cases where dF/dz = dF/dg(le)- dg(le)/dxjl # O, (1.8) there exists a marginal externality. This concept can be used to define explicitly external economies and diseconomies. A marginal external diseconomy exists when 5 dF/dz < O, (1.8a) i.e., a small change in the quantity of le used by j will change 2, which in turn will change the output level of i in the opposite direction. Similarly, a marginal external economy exists when dF/dz > O. (l.8b) An infra-marginal externality exists at all points where dF/Bz = O and equation (1.2) holds. (1.9) An infra-marginal external diseconomy exists when, for any g1ven set of values of xil’xi2""’xin’ 5Although I shall use dF/dz to represent the longer 'expression dF/ag(x. ).dg(x.l)/dx.l, its precise meaning should not be forgdéten. 3 j Z dF/dz = 0, f0 dF/dz dz < O, and equation (1.2) holds. (1.9a) This means that although small changes in 2 do not affect the total output of i, the total effect of j's use of le is to decrease i's output. Analogously, an infra-marginal external economy exists when, for any given set of values of X0 X0 0.. X. 11' 12’ ’ 1n’ Z dF/dz = 0, f0 dF/dz dz > O, and equation (1.2) holds. (1.9b) Now small changes in z = g(le) do not change i's total out— put, but the total effect of j's using le increases i's output.6 6The meaning of an infra—marginal externality can be clarified by considering an example. Let i's production function be 2 1/2 oi = (a -(x-1)2 - (z-l)2) Then the first-order conditions require in/dx = (l-x)/Qi = 0 where a > 0. and in/dz.= (1-z)/Qi = O. This implies that an extremum is found where x = l and z = l. S1nce szi/dx2 = - az/a3 < 0, 8203/822 = - az/a3 < O, and sz-/dxdz = O at the point where x = l and z = 1, then 1 (azoi/axz) (azoi/azz> > (szi/dxazlz- Therefore, the necessary and sufficient conditions for a maximum of Q. are fulfilled. It is clear that infinitesimal changes in 2 will not change i's output. But evaluation of 10 The classifications so far introduced resulted from evaluating the partial derivatives of i's production function with respect to 2 over the whole range of 2. Further con— cepts of relevance and irrelevance require considering the extent to which the externality-causing factor is used by the firm that has control over it, i.e., j. For an external- ity to be potentially relevant, the use of the externality- causing factor must create a desire on the part of i to change j's level of use. If an externality creates no such desire, it may be termed irrelevant. Formally, a potentially relevant marginal external diseconomy exists when dF/dz < O. (1.10) In this case, i would like j to decrease its use of le because that would decrease z and, consequently, increase i's output. Similarly, a pgtentially relevant marginal external economy exists when dF/dz > O. (1.11) I; aF/dz dz will show that j's use of x.l does have an effect on i's output: 3 f; (1—2)/Qi dz = (az-(x-1)2) (aZ-(x-l)2-l)l/2 > 0. Thus we have an example of an infra-marginal external econ- omy. The quantity of 2 would not normally be equal to one if j ignored its effect on 1. Hence we must suppose that either j made a mistake that resulted in z = l or that it 'was done purposely to increase social welfare. If the latter is the case, j was misguided because, as we shall see later, increasing 2 until dF/dz = 0 will not, in general, maximize social welfare. 1/2 ll Firm i would like j to increase its use of le for analogous reasons. The concepts of relevance and irrelevance may also be applied to infra—marginal externalities. Infra-marginal externalities are clearly irrelevant for small changes in the quantity of 2. But when discrete changes are introduced, i will want to alter the quantity j employs in all cases except when dF/dz = O and (1.12) F(Xil’xi2’°°"xin’le) Z_F(xil,xiz,...,xin,le) l jl' When equality holds in (1.12), i is getting the most for all le # 25 where E51 is the equilibrium quantity of x "good" or the least "bad" from j's use of input le. Although potential relevance depends upon i's desire to alter j's behavior, this does not imply that it is pos- sible to do so. But Pareto relevance of an externality does depend upon this possibility. Specifically, an externality is Pareto relevant when the quantity of z can be changed such that i is better off without making j worse off. In other words, if the externality is Pareto relevant, there are mutual benefits available. More formally, a marginal externality is Pareto relevant whenever lPi-dF/dzl > le-dG/dle - pl . (1.13) 12 This means that for i to be in a position to alter the quan- tity of le used, the value of the effect on i's operations must exceed the value of the benefit j receives less the cost of purchasing the input, i.e., the net increased bene- fit to i must exceed the net cost to j consequent upon j's reducing le from the present employment level. This dif- ference is available to i and j: so a change can be made that will make at least one better off without making the other worse off. From equation (1.7), if j is maximizing profits, Pj-dG/dle = pl when x. .Clearly then, when j is 31 = 3Ejl' maximizing profits, a potentially relevant marginal exter- nality must also be Pareto relevant because the right-hand side of inequality (1.13) vanishes. Thus there must be room for mutual benefits, i.e., both i and j can gain from some adjustment on j's part. From condition (1.13), it follows that for the production sector the condition for Pareto equilibrium when externalities are present is lPi°dF/dz = le°8G/dle — pl . (1.14) An extremely important implication of equation (1.14) is that Pareto equilibrium does not require the removal of the 13 externality.7 The opportunity for mutual benefit, however, is removed, i.e., the marginal externality is no longer Pareto relevant; the interests of the two firms are exactly offsetting. Instead of dealing with only two firms, we can also include situations where j's action affects a group of other firms. This modification really does not change anything except the conditions for Pareto relevance and Pareto equi- librium. In this case, Pareto relevance requires 5 z Pi°dFi/dz .- . - 1.1 i=1 > IPJ dG/dle pl ( 5) where Fi is the production function of the i-th firm. of course, we are still assuming that all firms are pure com- petitors in both the product and factor markets. Again, if j is in equilibrium, all marginal external- ities must be Pareto relevant since the right-hand side of inequality (1.15) will vanish. Under these circumstances, the condition for Pareto equilibrium is s . Z Pi-dFl/dzl = le°dG/5le - pl . (1.16) 1 7This demonstrates that the policy—maker cannot merely focus on the existence of an externality. He must determine whether it is Pareto relevant before he can make any decision. ‘ 14 The same comments that applied to equations (1.13) and (1.14) apply to these conditions. An additional point worth emphasizing is the joint- supply nature of externalities.8 As noted previously, 2 is supplied to 1 without charge. The reason no price is attached to z is that z is an accidental by-product of pro- ducing Qj' In many cases, by-products are sold by the firm that produces them; but in this instance, such is not the case because independent operation precludes j from knowing of its effect on 1. Since joint-supply characterizes j's operation, its production function should be re—stated: . = . + z = G x. ,x. ,...,x. . 1.17 Q3 Q3 (31 32 gm) ( ) In general, j could produce Qj independently; but when joint- supply occurs with a zero price for 2, we may assume that this is simply because it is more efficient than separate supply. To demonstrate this, define j's alternative cost functions as functions of output: C = h l where i = . + z, 1.18 1 1(0)) Q] Q] ( ) or 8This relation was pointed out by J. M. Buchanan in "Joint Supply, Externality and Optimality," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (1966), 404-415. I have merely adapted his develop— ments for my purposes. 15 c2 = h2(Qj) and c3 = h3(z). (1.19) Then the condition for the efficiency of joint-supply is given by acl/aoj < acz/an + ac3/az, (1.20) i.e., the marginal cost of producing Qj and 2 together is less than the sum of the marginal costs of producing them separately. Since equation (1.20) is not inconsistent with BCl/BQj > dCz/de, (1.21) 2 will be supplied without charge if, and only if, j finds it more efficient to produce 03 than Qj’ i.e., when acl/an g_ac2/aoj. (1.22) This follows from the necessary marginal conditions for exchange equilibrium under joint-supply: acl/an = Pj + Pz. (1.23) Clearly, when P2 = O and inequality (1.21) holds, there will be no joint-supply. In addition, we may note that any situation satisfying condition (1.22) automatically satisfied inequality (1.20). That is to say, the existence of an externality implies joint—supply. But we should also note that joint-supply does not necessarily imply the existence of an externality because joint-supply may exist 16 when (1.20) holds and the price of z is non-zero, even if (1.21) also holds. Finally, it is worthy of mention that when j sup- plies z to 1 without charge, input le becomes collective in a sense.9 When j buys and employs input x the output 2 jl' that is directly related to x. becomes available to i. Of 31 course, in the case of externalities, the factor 2 is imposed upon 1. This is analogous to some of the standard examples of collective goods, e.g., society decides it wants a certain amount of National Defense and whether or not I want any of it I am forced to consume it. The equilibrium condition for a collective input is the same as that which results from joint-profit maximization, viz., Pi°dF/dz + Pj°dG/dle = pl. (1.24) This condition merely states that the sum of the values of marginal products must equal the price of the input. Inspec- tion of equation (1.14), the condition for Pareto equilibrium when externalities are present, reveals that these two condi- tions are the same. These definitions are not strictly in accord with all the literature. For example, Bator would find them too 9The collective nature of such a factor was men— tioned by Charles Plott in "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (1966), 86. l7 restricted.lo He defines externality in a much broader sense as the existence of any phenomenon that precludes decentralized pricing from sustaining Pareto optimal outputs. While this discussion is limited to his first type, owner- ship externalities, Bator also includes technical external- ities and public good externalities. Technical external- ities are a consequence of indivisibilities or smoothly increasing returns to scale, which cause non-convexity of the set of feasible input-output points. The result is the natural monopoly case where decentralized competitive pric- ing cannot sustain Pareto optimal outputs because perpetual losses would be incurred. On the other hand, public goods supposedly preclude the existence of a set of prices asso- ciated with the point of maximum social welfare that would sustain the Pareto optimal output configuration, i.e., the exclusion principle fails to be operative. We have seen that this concept is not wholly at variance with our own. In fact, there must be some element of "publicness" in any instance of direct interaction in production because of the externality-causing input's collective nature. 1OF. M. Bator, "Market Failure." 18 2. The Effect of an Externality In the absence of externalities, the transformation relation between inputs and outputs for society may be given in implicit form as X ,...,X) =0, (2.1) T(Yl,Y 2 m 2,...,Yn;Xl, where the Yi represent the total amounts of society's n out— puts at full employment and the Xj represent the total amounts of society's m inputs. This transformation function is a surface in n-space that shows the maximum amount of any one YR given the values of the other Yi's and the Xj's. Thus to increase Y1, for example, we must decrease some other output, or outputs, if we hold constant the amounts of inputs employed.ll Let us now introduce the externality discussed in the previous section, viz., the one specified in equation (1.2). The externality will change the transformation func- tion to X X * . T (Yl’Y n+1! l'l 2I'°°I Yn’Y Xm) = O, (2.2) 2,..., where Yn is the output 2. Assuming that i produces only +1 Y1, that the externality is a diseconomy, and that its effects are confined to i, the transformation surface will llSee P. Samuelson, Foundations of Economic Analysis (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1963), p. 230. 19 be lowered in the Yl—direction. In the case of an external economy, it will be raised in the Yl-direction. Thus when there is a change in the technical relation between inputs and outputs, our frame of reference concerning Pareto effi- ciency is different. After introducing the externality, Pareto efficiency in production requires that society operate on surface T*: and we can ignore surface T as it is no longer relevant. When the condition for Pareto equilibrium is fulfilled, we shall be on surface T* even though a marginal externality exists; but if a Pareto relevant marginal externality exists, we shall be operating below the surface T*. Clearly, resources are not allocated properly when there exists a Pareto relevant marginal externality. It should be stressed that whatever the optimal adjustment is for an external dis— economy, its existence implies that society is worse off than it would be without the diseconomy in the sense of there being less output.12 We should also note that introducing an externality does not also introduce a second-best situation. The theory of the second-best involves cases where society is operating below the relevant transformation surface and for some 12The effect of an externality on the production .possibility surface was noted by E. J. Mishan in "Reflec- tions on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects," The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, XXXI (1965), 105, 113, 114. 20 reason cannot remove the impediment to Pareto optimality. Satisfaction of equation (1.14), the condition for Pareto equilibrium, implies that some method has been found for removing the obstacle from society's path to Pareto effi- ciency; society is doing the best that it can. Simply because surface T* is not the same as surface T does not mean that we are in the foggy realm of the second-best. What it does mean is that there has been a change in the technical conditions underlying production. With such a change, it no longer makes any sense to talk about Pareto optimality in the absence of externalities because the marginal externality does not disappear in equilibrium as equation (1.14) shows. The externality-free transformation surface T is no longer relevant. Society must live with the technically feasible surface T*. On the other hand, if, for some reason, the Pareto relevance of the marginal externality cannot be removed, then society will operate below surface T*, and we have a second-best problem. 3. Solutions for the Externalitnyroblem We know that an efficient allocation of resources requires operation on the transformation surface T*. What prevents the attainment of surface T* is the Pareto rele- vance of the externality caused by 2. Any solution to this 'problem must involve removing the Pareto relevance found in equation (1.13), i.e., a solution must result in Pareto 21 equilibrium. As the previous sections pointed out, this does not require removal of the externality. In fact, we must live with it. But this does not mean that simply ignoring the externality constitutes a solution because that would not lead us to a Pareto optimum. .Such a second-best approach is appropriate only when the costs of achieving efficiency exceed the gains.13 Assume that the problem is defined by equations (1.1), (1.2), (l.8a), and (1.13), i.e., there exists an external diseconomy and independent profit maximization demonstrates that it is Pareto relevant. We can discuss the following types of solutions: bargaining, taxes and subsidies, and mergers. 131 might point out here that we can avoid intro— ducing the costs of adjusting to the presence of the exter- nality only if we assume that the pricing system works smoothly, i.e., without cost. This assumption is not strictly legitimate as it is clear that some resources must be expended in making the adjustments. If the costs of adjustment vary with output, we must add them to the social marginal cost. Their effect will be to reduce optimal out— put further. On the other hand, if they are lump sum, the decrease in social loss from removing the Pareto relevance of the external diseconomy must exceed the lump sum cost for the adjustment to be worthwhile. (On the costs of solution, see Mishan, "Reflections," p. 111, and R. H. Coase, "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and Economics, October 1960, pp. 2, 15—19.) In the subsequent discussion of external diseconomies we shall assume that the costs are lump sum and that the adjustment is worthwhile. Further, the discussion will primarily deal with external disecon- omies as the treatment of external economies is quite .symmetrical. 22 Bargaining One approach to solving the problem is through direct bargaining between i and j. Three comments on bar- gaining are in order: first, bargaining is most feasible when the number of firms involved is not too large. In our case of two firms this presents no difficulty, but the results of this analysis cannot be taken to apply in all cases without recognizing the problems inherent in large- group decisions. .Second, the form that the bargaining process will take depends upon the property rights defined exogenously by law, i.e., the direction of payment depends upon who is liable to whom. We will take the law as given and discuss the problem around it. Third, throughout this entire thesis, I shall exclusively deal with the production sector. Because bargaining involves confrontations of pro— ducers, we must assume that these discussions concerning the employment of resources in no way affects the markets for final output. Since i is suffering from an external diseconomy imposed upon it by j, from i's point of view, it will appear that j has chosen the "incorrect" quantity of le. Recall that fulfilling condition (1.13) means i desires a change in the behavior of j and it is possible to induce such a change, possible in the sense that there is a mutually advantageous alternative. 23 We can see the effect the law will have on the bargaining process by considering several legal arrangements separately. Let us begin with the assumptions that the law imposes no legal constraints on j, the firm that creates the externality, and that we are concerned with an external dis- economy, i.e., dF/dz < 0. The presumption is that i offers to pay j $B for each unit of le that j does not use, i.e., is the amount of j will receive $B(X§ -le) from i where'fi. 1 31 input le that j would otherwise use. Since 1 cannot know the precise form of j's production function, the offer must only be a tentative one. If the offer of $B per unit does not result in an optimum for i, the offer will be withdrawn and further offers will be made until an optimum is reached. Formally, the offer of a bribe changes the profit functions for i and j to n . = P.°G x. ,x. ,...,x. + B X1 -x. - 'x. 3.1 and n ”1 = Pi°F(xil,xi2,...,xin,z) - B(le-le) -k:lpk°xik.(3.2) Because of the change to conditions (3.1) and (3.2» the first-order conditions for a profit maximum also change. These conditions for j are now Pj'dG/Bxjk - pk = 0 1f xjk > 0 (k = 2,3,...,n) (3.3) and 24 Pj-dG/ale - (pl+B) = 0 if x > 0. (3.4) jl Since pl < (pl+B), le < le, i.e., Since the bribe offer increases the "effective" market price of le, that j employs will decrease. This is the direction of the quantity change i desired, but the magnitude of the change may not be sufficient for the attainment of surface T*. To determine this we must investigate the effect on i's first-order conditions: Pi'dF/Bxik — p = 0 if x. > 0 (k k 1k l,2,...,n) (3.5) and . S. Pi aF/az + B {5.) 0. (3.6) If "<" holds, a further decrease in j's use of le is desired by i and a new offer B will be made such that B'> B. If ">" holds, the first offer made was too large and j decreased its use of le A A Firm i will then make a new offer B such that B < B. by more than the optimum amount. Finally, if "=" holds, there is no incentive for i to make a new offer because he has already made the offer most profitable to him. We should recognize that the first offer may not be the correct one because, although i may know the exact value of Pi'dF/dz, it may not know the exact Achange that will occur in the quantity of 2 as a result of a decrease in the usage of le. In other words, i may not know the precise form of the relation 2 = g(le). Thus this 25 bargaining process will continue until equality holds in equation (3.6) and equilibrium is attained. When equations (3.3), (3.4), and (3.5) hold and there is equality in equa— tion (3.6), we have a Pareto optimum. Neither firm can be made better off without making the other worse off. More formally, we can solve equation (3.6) for B and substitute into equation (3.4) to get Pj°dG/ale + Pi-dF/dz - p1 = 0. (3.7) This will be recognized as exactly the same as equation (1.24) and essentially the same as equation (1.14). Thus bargaining has led us to Pareto equilibrium in the presence of a marginal externality. Note, however, that the exter- nality has not been removed. Now let us consider the same problem, except that the law does not allow j to impose an externality upon 1 in the absence of i's consent. That is, the law prescribes le = O. For a problem to exist under these circumstances we must have A Pj-dG/dle - p1 > 0 for le < le (3.8) /\ where le is the quantity of le that would make an equality hold in expression (3.8). Consequently, j has an incentive to bribe i for permission to use le. The offer of a bribe to i changes the profit functions to n ”i = Pi°F(xil,xiz,...,xin,z) + ijl -kilpk-xik (3.9) 26 and n ) -(B+pl) le - Z pk°Xjk. (3.10) w. = P.-G(x. ,x. ,...,x. 3 3]- 32 k=2 3 3n Since i will suffer the inconvenience of j's use of le, i will presumably specify indirectly the quantity of le that j may use for a payment of B per unit. Firm i's speci- fication must be indirect because the precise relation 2 = g(le) may not be known to i. At any rate, offers will be made and rejected until the first—order conditions are satisfied: Pi'dF/dxik - p = 0 if x. > 0, (k = l,2,...,n) (3.11) k 1k Pi-dF/dz + B = 0, (3.12) Pj°dG/dxjk — pk = 0 1f xjk > 0, (k = 2,...,n) (3.13) and Pj-dG/dle - (B+pl) = 0 1f le > 0. (3.14) Since all we changed was the legal constraint, we can compare this equilibrium with the previous one. Interestingly, equa- tions (3.3), (3.4), (3.5), and (3.6) correspond to equations (3.13), (3.14), (3.11), and (3.12). Moreover, we can solve equation (3.12) for B, substitute into equation (3.14), and derive a relation exactly like equation (3.7). Of course, the same comments that applied to equation (3.7) also apply to this condition. 27 An intermediate case could be analyzed, one in which the law permits j some use of le and, therefore, some out— put 2. Davis and Whinston handle this case and find that although both firms may attempt bribes initially, there will come a stage in the bargaining process when both will real- ize which firm must pay in order to reach an equilibrium. In conclusion, when bargaining is feasible, i.e., when the number of parties is not too large, a Pareto optimum can be attained without outside interference. The question of what the legal constraints ought to be is a question of equity and does not have a bearing on the ques- tion of efficiency. But once the legal constraint for lia- bility is specified, no further legal constraints should be imposed because they might prevent the firms from reaching an optimal solution. In other words, all the law should do is make clear the liability for externalities since bargain- ing can then move society to a Pareto optimum position.l4 Taxes and Subsidies An alternative to bargaining is the tax-subsidy approach. In general, this solution involves taxing the firm that causes the externality and compensating the firm 14This entire discussion of bargaining depends heavily on O. A. Davis and A. B. Whinston, "Some Notes on - Equating Private and Social Cost," The Southern Economic Journal, October 1965, pp. 113-126.—IR. H. Coase in "Social Cost" also deals with bargaining and the effect of legal constraints on income distribution. 28 suffering the externality in like amounts. But as Plott points out, it is important to levy the tax on the correct thing.15 In our example, j causes the externality when it produces Qj’ but Qj is not the culprit. The source of dif- ficulty is 2, which is a joint- or by-product of Qj' Since 2 is a function of input le, the tax should be placed on 2 or on the use of input le. In fact, levying the tax on Qj will result in an increase in 2 when le is an inferior input. Plott demonstrated this result graphically for a two-factor production function, but it can be generalized to n inputs. Input inferiority will be dealt with in detail in the next chapter. Obviously, taxing the offending firm inherently presumes a legal constraint which places the burden on that firm. The result of such a tax—subsidy scheme is the iden- tical resource allocation and income distribution that pri— vate bargaining yields when the law specifies?jl = 0 in the absence of i's permission for it to be otherwise. To show this formally, all we must do is let B represent both the tax on j and the payment to i in equations (3.9) through (3.14). Now equation (3.12) states that the compensation is exactly equal to the damage done by j to i. In addition, by solving equation (3.12) for B and substituting into equation (3.14) we get condition (3.7): 15 pp. 84—86. C- Plott, "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," 29 Pj°dG/dle + Pi-dF/dz — p1 = 0. Rearranging this equation we get Pj'dG/ale pl — Pi-BF/Bz. (3.15) In words, j must equate the value of the marginal product of le with its price plus the value of the damage it does to i's operation. Now the social value of the marginal product of le is equated with its price. In addition to the factor inferiority objection to levying the tax on Qj' we can now see another objection. Levying the tax on Qj so that condition (3.15) is satisfied will render j's choices for all other inputs non-optimal. Taxing Qj changes j's profit function to n w. = P.’G x. ,x. ,...,x. — 2 -x. - tQ., 3.16 3 J (31 32 3n) k=lpk 3k 3 ( ) where t is the per unit tax. The first—order conditions now become a - OX. = P.°OG X- " _ t = 00 At the margin, the tax is levied on each input; therefore, j does not equate the social values of the marginal products with their respective input prices except for factor le. 30 Thus equation (3.15) is fulfilled, but all the other input conditions are violated.16 In the absence of a good reason for supposing the government has some special knowledge of the precise forms of the production functions, we may assume that it must arrive at the appropriate tax or subsidy throngh some iter- ative procedure much like that used in the bargaining solu- tion. Thus the difference between the private bargaining and the tax-subsidy approaches is that the government is an intermediary. One very important point should be stressed: if j is to be taxed, an amount equal to the tax must be paid to 1. When i is not so compensated, there remains a Pareto relevant marginal externality, i.e., there is room for further bargain- ing.l7 We can easily show this by supposing that a tax is levied on j and no compensation is made to i. Firm j's decision calculus changes because its profit function is altered to n w. = P.-G x. ,x. ,...,x. — B+ x. — x. 3.17 J J (31 32 gm) < P1) 31 kizpk 3k < ) where B is the tax on j's use of le. Now for each value that B takes on, the marginal condition for le is l6C. Plott, "Corrective Taxes." Plott touched on this point, but did not demonstrate it explicitly. 17This was most clearly shown by Buchanan and Stubble- bine, "Externality" and R. Turvey, "On Divergences between Social Cost and Private Cost," Economica, N.S. XXX (1963) 309-313. 31 dwj/dle = Pj-dG/dle — (B+pl) = O. (3.18) Recall the definition of Pareto relevance and modify it to account for the tax: ‘Pi-dF/dzl > lpj~ae/ale — pl — B . (3.19) Firm j will select quantities of le to fulfill condition (3.18), but i cannot maximize its profits because dF/dz < 0 for all x. jl until the externality is completely removed. Of course, > 0, i.e., condition (3.19) will always hold removing the externality requires levying a prohibitive tax on the use of le. Until le = 0, room for bargaining will exist; therefore, Pareto equilibrium will not be reached 18 unless x. = 0 so long as i is not compensated. jl Mergers A third solution is the merger alternative. So far, the desired change in resource allocation has been accom— plished through market transactions: directly via bargain- ing and indirectly via government tax-subsidy decisions. A merger will accomplish the same result by substituting an entrepreneurial decision for a market transaction. That the 18This tax-subsidy alternative is dealt with or touched upon by Davis and Whinston, "Some Notes"; Coase, "Social Cost"; 0. A. Davis and A. B. Whinston, "External- ities, Welfare, and the Theory of Games," Journal of Polit- ical Economy, June 1962, pp. 241—262; Buchanan and Stubble- bine, "Externality"; Turvey, "On Divergences"; and Mishan, "Reflections." 32 result will be the same is fairly easy to demonstrate. We have seen that Pareto relevant marginal externalities permit gains from trade to exist. And we have also seen that reap- ing these gains through either the proper imposition of taxes and subsidies or bargaining yields a Pareto optimum resource allocation. Since this final equilibrium is exactly the same as the joint-profit maximizing solution, a merger clearly offers the same resource allocation. But recall that bargaining resulted in the two firms' sharing the gains from trade. In this important respect, division of the spoils, the merger approach more closely resembles the bargaining solution than the tax-subsidy solution. Of course, this will appear in the terms of the merger agree- ment. The effect of the merger is to internalize the externality so that account is taken of its existence when output decisions are made. Therefore, whenever the adminis— trative costs of the new, single firm are less than the costs of bargaining that it replaces, we should expect a merger to occur. Continuing to deal with a unilateral, or non- reciprocal, externality, we must realize that where the incentive to merge lies depends upon the legal framework. ‘When the law specifies that the offending firm is liable for damages, the offending firm will be the one interested in a merger. On the other hand, if the law specifies no such 33 liability, the damaged firm will be anxious to merge. If 0 I I 19 we con31der a mutual, or rec1procal, externality, i.e., i imposes an externality on j and j imposes an externality on i, the likelihood of a merger is increased. The reason for the increased likelihood is obvious: a merger is now bene- ficial to both firms. And so long as the market structure remains competitive, the merger is beneficial to society 0 I I 20 because optimal resource allocation is ensured. 4. Cost Functions and Reciprocal Externalities The existence of externalities can be represented by including an output of another firm in the cost function of the affected firm.21 This alternative view is worth discuss- ing because it sheds some light on a few difficulties that have yet to be mentioned. The amount of difficulty we shall encounter depends primarily upon whether the externalities are unilateral or reciprocal and whether the cost functions 19Mutual externalities are explored in more detail in the next section. 20The merger solution was suggested by Coase, "Social Cost": Davis and Whinston, "Theory of Games"; and Mishan, "Reflections." 210n the derivation of cost functions, see J. M. Henderson and R. E. Quandt, Microeconomic Theory (New York: NmGraw-Hill Book Company, 1958), pp. 55-62, 66-67. 34 are separable or non-separable.22 Let us begin with the easier cases and proceed to the more difficult. Unilateral Externalities When the externality is unilateral the cost function of 1 includes an output of j, but j's cost function depends only upon its own output. This is essentially the case that has been discussed so far; however, by inspecting the effect on the cost function, we can see a little more clearly the effects of an externality on the firm's operation. Consider an external diseconomy. Firm i‘s cost function is Ci = Ci(Qi.Z), (4-1) and j's cost function is C. = C. E 4.2 3 3(93) ( ) where Qi is the output of i, z is the externality-causing by- product of firm j, and Q5 represents the joint products Qj and 2. Since i cannot control the quantity of z, the first- order conditions for independent profit maximization are Pi = Sci/SQi and Pj = acj/an. (4.3) 2Reciprocal externalities and the distinction ibetween separable and non-separable functions are handled in detail by Davis and Whinston, "Theory of Games." 35 For Pareto equilibrium, this resource allocation must correspond to that of joint-profit maximization. It is quite obvious that this is not the case since the joint profit function in the competitive case is 77- = Pi'Qi + Ppoj " Ci(Qir Z) " Cj (Qj)! (404') and the first—order conditions are aw/aoi = Pi — Sci/SQi = 0, (4.5) and a i = P. - 5c. 5 1 — ac. 52 = 0. 57/ Q3 3 3/ Q3 1/ If Sci/dz # 0, conditions (4.5) are not the same as condi- tions (4.3), and non-optimal output decisions are made because the deleterious effect of z is ignored. Any function, f(yl,y2,...,ynL is termed "separable" if and only if f(yl.y2.....yn) = fl(y1) + f2(y2) + ..- + fn(yn). (4.6) In our case, Ci = Ci(Qi’z) is separable if and only if Ci(Qi’z) = Cil(Qi) + Ci2(z). (4.7) VVhen this is the case, the marginal cost of producing Qi is Ilnambiguously defined as dCil/in, i.e., as a function Shalely of its own output. The consequence of separability iis that, although the total cost of i is a function of two 36 variables, the marginal cost for i is unaffected by changes in 2. In graphical terms, the height of the total cost curve varies with changes in 2, but the slope is the same at all levels of output. In other words, if TCi is the total cost curve for Q; = 0, Tc: = TCi + k for some Q; > 0 where k is constant. Of course, as Q; varies, the value of k will vary. Since the marginal costs are not affected in this case, there exists a unique output which will maximize i's profit regardless of the level of z. The only relevance that the level of 2 has lies in its effect on i's total profit. The greater is z, the smaller is vi. But all this does not mean that the externality has no allocative effects.23 Clearly, if j takes account of the effect that 2 has on the profits of i there will be a different resource allocation. When the externality enters i's cost function in a multiplicative way the separability condition (4.7) is not satisfied and the cost function is said to be "non—separa— 24 ble." The effect of non-separability is that when 2 changes the total cost curve is not vertically displaced 23O. A. Davis and A. B. Whinston, "On Externalities, Information and the Government-Assisted Invisible Hand," _§conomica, N.S. XXXIII (1966), 304-305. 24In Appendix A, I derived the cost function of a firm with a Cobb—Douglas production function and of one with a CBS production function. Neither production function yields a separable cost function. 37 by a constant amount. The total cost curve will be altered in some way such that the marginal cost will be affected. Firm i can no longer define its marginal cost unambiguously without first knowing the value of 2 since marginal cost is now a function of its own output and the output of j. There- fore, i must know the value of 2 before it can make the correct allocative decisions. But once it knows the value of z, i can proceed to maximize its profits as best it can. So far, the cost function alternative has no real impact on anything done before this section. But this exer- cise has pointed out that when the cost functions are separa— ble, the external effects do not affect i marginally. On the other hand, non-separable cost functions plus external- ities will give rise to changes at the margin. As long as we retain the assumption of unilateral external effects, no new problem arises and all the externality solutions apply. Mutual Externalities When externalities are mutual, j's output affects i's cost function and vice versa, i.e., the cost functions become C- = Ci(Qi.Z) (4.8) and C- =Cj(Qj.y) (4.9) 38 where y is an externality—causing by-product of 1. Here, again, independent profit maximization yields Pi = dCi/in and Pj = de/de (4.10) as first-order conditions because each firm can only maximize profits with respect to the variables under its control. Comparing conditions (4.10) with the joint profit maximizing conditions "U ll aci/BQi + acj/ay (4.11) and '1?! ll acj/aoj + aci/az reveals that non-optimal decisions are made. The effect of separability in the mutual external- ities case is to leave the marginal costs of both firms unchanged regardless of the quantities of y and 2. Thus i and j can unambiguously define their respective marginal costs in terms of their own outputs, and, therefore, there exist unique outputs which will maximize the profits of i and j individually. This means that one firm's output deci— sion is wholly independent of the other firm's decision. Since non-optimal decisions are made, we are inter- ested in solutions to these problems. For a tax-subsidy scheme to constitute a solution, the government must be able 'to find the correct outputs for i and j. It can do this by 39 solving the necessary conditions (4.11) for Qiand OS. If we let t represent the per unit tax and?)i and 65 the optimal outputs, the correct tax is given by "d l ”- ll BCi/in (4.12) P ' t 0 EEC 0 a 3 . Inspection of equations (4.11) makes it clear that the tax on each firm should equal the damage done to the other firm. As before, the tax collected must be paid to the damaged firm. In a similar manner, the bargaining procedure can be carried out. Optimal output decisions will now follow because each firm is made aware of its effects on the prof- its of the other firm. We should recognize that, when the cost functions are separable and there are mutual external- ities, the optimal solution simply involves removing the Pareto relevance of each externality separately. In other words, we can deal with one external effect at a time. When the cost functions are non-separable and the externalities are reciprocal we encounter a bit of a problem. Since the marginal cost of each firm depends upon the output decision of the other firm, each firm would like to wait for ‘the other firm to commit itself before making its own deci- Sion. It is fairly easy to appreciate this fact when one <20nsiders that i's output decision changes whenever j's 40 output decision changes and the same is true for j. Such a situation introduces a measure of uncertainty into each firm's decision calculus. This certainly can be removed by internalizing the externalities through a merger of the firms. So long as the post-merger market structure remains competitive, a merger would prove to be mutually beneficial to the two firms and socially desirable since optimal output decisions would be ensured. Moreover, this solution may very well be the most practical. A tax-subsidy scheme might also be devised if the government knows the cost functions of the two firms. The solution involves finding new cost functions ci and cj for the firms such that these new cost functions are single— valued functions of "own" output and they account for all social costs.25 Then the use of these new cost functions is supposed to solve all the problems. But Davis and Whinston have pointed out some rather serious difficulties with this method.26 For the new cost functions to account for all social costs, dci/in = dCi/in + acj/ay (4.13) 25This proposal was suggested in S. Wellisz, "On External Diseconomies and the Government-Assisted Invisible IHand," Economica, N.S. XXXI (1964), 358-359. 26 Davis and Whinston, "On Externalities," pp. 307-312. 41 and dcj/de = aci/az + acj/aoj (4.14) must be satisfied. But if the cost functions are non-separa- ble, the terms on the right-hand side of (4.13) are func- tions of Qi and Qj' Therefore, the domain of Qj would have to be restricted for the function to be single-valued. There is, however, no a priori reason why the domain of Qj should be restricted. If we ignore this problem, what remains is to find Ql as a function of Qj and Qj as a function of Qi' This involves solving partial differential equations where no truly general method of solution exists. But assuming the equations can be solved, we would have 01 = hj(Qj) and Qj = hi(Qi)' (4.15) Each of these functions involves a constant of integration. Since hi and hj represent the taxes or subsidies, correct values for these constants must be found. Finding these values requires solving the joint profit maximization prob- lem for the optimal outputs'—Q-i and'Oj and substituting into equations (4.15). Then the new cost functions are, by substitution, ci = Ci(Qi.hi(Qi)) and cj = Cj(Qj.hj(Qj)). (4.16) 42 Supposing that we have assumed away all the problems or have overcome them in some way and the new cost functions (4.16) have been found, the coup de grace may now be applied: there is no way that the government can force the firms to use these new cost functions. In all the previous cases it was in each firm's interest to move to the socially optimal output, but in this case the firm may not believe that using the prescribed cost function will not hurt it. If each firm was previously aware of the other firm's influence on its cost function, they may not believe that the costs are truly independent now. Moreover, if, e.g., i does not believe this and produces some Qi fi'ai, j will experience costs that the new function, c., does not reflect. This experience would certainly lend credence to any skepticism j previously held with respect to the efficacy of using the new cost function. From this discussion, one can readily appreciate the difficulties inherent in the case of mutual externalities with non-separable cost functions. Davis and Whinston go on to discuss an iterative procedure which purports to take care of this case. But the authors admit that they know hnothing about the speed with which the procedure will con- Verge to an equilibrium. Although I do not intend to go into this problem any further, it is worth recognizing the difficulties that this case presents; especially when a 43 merger is not permitted by the requirement of maintaining a competitive market structure.27 5. Second-Order Conditions28 To this point, we have focused our attention on the first-order conditions for a profit maximum and have neglect- ed the second-order conditions. But these second-order con- ditions can be ignored no longer since satisfaction of the first—order conditions does not ensure a maximum. We can approach this problem through the firm's cost function. Because profit is the difference between total revenue (R) and total cost (C), the profit function for i is Tri = R(Qi) - Ci(Qinle21 ...,Pn) . (5.1) Of course, optimum output occurs when profit is maximized. Assuming the functions are twice differentiable, this requires awi/aoi = aR/aoi - aci/aoi = 0 (5.2) and 2 2 _ 2 2 2 2 a wi/aoi — a R/aQi — a ci/BQi < 0. (5.3) 27Mishan pointed out in "Reflections" that the crux of this problem lies as much in the assumption of reciprocal externalities as in the assumption of non-separable cost functions. 28Most of this discussion is based on Samuelson, QEQundations, pp. 57-62, 76-78 and Appendix A, pp. 357-379. 44 Equation (5.2) says that marginal revenue equals marginal cost at equilibrium. But this is not enough because equat- ing marginal revenue and marginal cost will yield minimum profits when the slope of the marginal revenue curve exceeds the slope of the marginal cost curve. This event is ruled out by requiring that condition (5.3) be satisfied. Then, the optimum output, 6:, is found by solving equation (5.2). Using cost functions assumes that they express the least total cost for each level of output. For the total costs of producingai to be a minimum the marginal produc- tivity of the last dollar spent must be equal in all uses, 29 i.e., that dF/dxik 8F/5(-z) l/lx = T — T— . (k = l,2,...,n) (5.4) These are the first—order conditions found in the con— strained cost minimization problem. Since we assume that costs are a minimum for each output level, these equations must hold when a; is produced. Samuelson3O has shown that A = MC, i.e., Pk B MC=7\ =W=W (k= l,2,...,n) (5.5) It seems that all we must add to the assumption of perfectly competitive pricing is diminishing marginal productivity and 29See Samuelson, Foundations, p. 60. On the sign of 2, see my Appendix B. 30Samuelson, Foundations, pp. 65-66. 45 we will then ensure satisfaction of the second-order condi- tion (5.3). This, however, is not true. We must have dimin- ishing marginal productivity, but we need something more. The "something more" did not show up because we assumed that the second—order conditions were satisfied in equations (5.4) and (5.5), but these equations are not sufficient to ensure a minimum. Consider i's profit function where all the inputs are considered independent variables. Let Vi = Pi-F(xll,xiz,...,xin,(z—z)) n (5.6) 31 - Z P 'X B(X -x ). k=1 k k 1 1 As before, the first-order conditions are dwi/dxik = Pi°dF/8xik - pk = 0 (k = l,2,...,n) (5.7) and 0. dwi/d(-z) = PidF/d(—z) - B Since Pi is marginal revenue, this again says that marginal revenue equals marginal cost in equilibrium. But it is well known that "a regular relative maximum requires that the quadratic form whose coefficients are the second partial 31For this slight re-formulation of i's profit function, see Appendix B. 46 derivatives be negative definite."32 It can be shown that the negative definiteness of this quadratic form implies that the principal minors of the Hessian determinant of the profit function must alternate in sign beginning with nega- tive. Since Pi > O and it appears in every term, we may ignore it and write the Hessian as F11 F12 '°° Fln F12 F12 F22 °'° an F22 2 2 s 2 F1n F2n °°' an Fnz Flz F22 "' Fnz Fzz where Fhk = sz/dxihdxik (h,k = 1,2,...,n,z). Because the first principal minor, F11, must be negative, we can con- clude that the marginal productivity of factor xi1 must be decreasing. Since the numbering of inputs is wholly arbi- trary, this condition must be invariant under any renumber- ing of inputs. Therefore, all Fkk must be negative. Thus, we have diminishing marginal productivity again. But this is still not enough. There could be a situation where increases in all factors will yield an increase in profits. Therefore, we also require that the decrease in a factor's "own" marginal productivity outweighs the positive effects on the marginal products of the other factors. For clarity, consider a two-input case. The Hessian will then be 32Samuelson,§oundations, p. 360. 47 F11 F12 H = . (5.9) F12 F22 . 2 For a max1mum, we need Fll < 0 and F11 F22 — (F12) > 0. The second inequality implies Fll-F22 > (F12)2. We can see that the "cross" effects of increasing both factors xil and xi2 must be outweighed by the "own" effects. When these conditions are satisfied the marginal cost curve will inter- sect the marginal revenue curve from below and the solution will represent a maximum of profit. For our purposes, we will assume that these second-order conditions are satisfied in all final equilibria. This is not an unreasonable assump- tion since we are just assuming away saddle points and per- petual losses. Saddle points are assumed away by convention and perpetual losses by common sense. CHAPTER III THE CONCEPT OF INFERIOR INPUTS In the preceding chapter we encountered the concept of inferior inputs. We shall examine this concept in more detail in the present chapter. Although Professor Hicks alluded to something akin to inferior inputs, D. V. T. Bear first defined inferior inputs in a formal manner. Bear developed his definition under the assumption of competition in the commodity and factor markets. But he did not explore the concept much beyond the definition. In an article soon to appear in Economica, C. E. Ferguson generalized Bear's work to include imperfect competition in the commodity mar— ket. In addition, Ferguson extended the concept by investi— gating the consequences that input inferiority has on other relations. Charles Plott's contribution was to demonstrate graphically the significance of inferior inputs with respect to measures taken to correct externality-caused resource misallocation.l 1J. R. Hicks, Value and Capital (2d ed.; Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1962), pp. 93-94. D. V. T. Bear, "Inferior Inputs and the Theory of the Firm," Journal of Political Economy, LXXIII (1965), 287—89. C. E. Ferguson, "'Inferior Factors' and the Theories of Production and Input Demand," Economica, to appear May 1968. Charles Plott, "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," Economica, XXXIII (1966), 84—87. 48 49 To explore these developments, we shall first set out a model of jointly-derived demand functions for inputs under general competitive conditions. Then we shall intro- duce the definition of inferior inputs and investigate some of the consequences of input inferiority. l. A Basic Model of Input Demand Assume that a firm sells its output under competi- tive conditions and produces its output according to the twice differentiable production function Q = f(xl.x2....,xn). (1.1) where Q is total output and x1.. is the quantity of input 1. Competition in the commodity market implies that the firm's total revenue is R P°Q = P°f(xl,x2,...,xn), (1.2) where P is the commodity price. Competition in the factor markets implies that the firm accepts the input prices as given. Defining profit as the difference between total cost and total revenue, the firm's profit function may be written as n w = P~f(xl,x2,...,xn) -i:lpixi, (1-3) where pi is the price of input 1. The firm attempts to 50 maximize profit by selecting appropriate quantities of the n inputs. The first-order conditions for a profit maximum are obtained by differentiating (1.3) with respect to xi: dW/dxi = P-f. — p. = O, (i = l,2,...,n) (1.4) where fi = df/dxi. That is, in equilibrium the price of each input must equal the value of its marginal product. Equations (1.4) represent the n jointly-derived input demand functions in implicit form. The second-order conditions for a regular relative maximum to exist at the point in n-space where the n first partial derivatives vanish require d w = Z Z (BZTr/dxi-dxj)dxi dxj < 0, (1.5) 13' i.e., the quadratic form must be negative definite. The determinant of (1.5) is Pfll Pf12 ... Pfln Pfl2 Pf22 ... Pf2n N = = Pn F*, (1.6) Pf1n Pf2n ... ann where fij = azf/axi-ij. Since P appears in every term, we may ignore P and consider F*. It is well known that the negative definiteness of (1.5) implies that the principal minors of F* must alternate in sign beginning with 51 f11 < 0. Without loss of generality, we may assume n is even. Thus F* > 0. Since the numbering of the inputs obviously should not matter, assume that the price of input 1 changes while the prices of the other n - 1 inputs are held constant. To observe the effect of changes in pl, differentiate the first- order conditions (1.4) with respect to pl. In matrix form, the result is r' r ' — 7 £11 £12 ... fln axl/apil l/P f12 f22 ... f2n dxz/dpl 0 . . . . = . . (1.7) hfln f2n ... fnn hpxn/dp¥_ ._0 The determinant of the coefficient matrix in (1.7) is pre- cisely the F* of equation (1.6). Equations (1.7) can be solved by Cramer's Rule: = . * axl/apl Fil/P F , (1.8) where F11 is the cofactor of the l - 1 element in F*. Since F* and P are positive, . = . * Sign dxl/dpl Sign Fll' (1.9) But sign F11 = — sign F* (1.10) because F* is negative definite. Thus 52 axl/apl = Ffl/P-F* < 0, (1.11) i.e., the quantity of input 1 demanded is inversely related to its price. Moreover, because the selection of input 1 was wholly arbitrary we may conclude that this holds for all inputs: ax./ap. = F#./P°F* < 0. (j = l,2,...,n) (1.12) 3 J 33 Similarly, solving for dxj/dpl yields = * o * axj/apl Flj/P F . (1.13) Further, ° * dxj/dpl Z 0 according as Flj Z 0. (1.14) Thus, a priori we cannot say anything about the Sign of 2 dxj/dpl. 2. Inferior Inputs In words, an input is termed inferior if and only if an increase in its price leads to an increase in the optimal output of the firm.3 From the production function (1.1), input 1 is inferior if and only if 2This entire section is simply an adaptation of a model developed by C. E. Ferguson in a manuscript entitled "Neo-Classical Theory of Production and Distribution," to be published by Cambridge University Press, January 1969. 3Bear, "Inferior Inputs . . .," p. 287. 53 ao/apl =. 3 “MS lfj-axj/apl > o. (2.1) This result can be expressed in more familiar terms, however. First, differentiate the first-order conditions (1.4) with respect to P, the commodity price. The result is fi + P i fij dxj/BP = 0. (j = l,2,...,n) (2.2) Equations (2.2) may be written in matrix form as f11 f12 ... fln OXl/OP ‘ fl f12 f22 ... f2n dxz/BP f2 . o ' o : = — l/P . (2 o 3) _f In f2n . . . fnn— laXn/apr _an The negative definite determinant of the coefficient matrix in (2.3) is F*=f >0. (i,j .1,2,...,rn (2.4) 13' Clearly, the F* of (2.4) is identically the F* of (1.6). Using (2.4) and Cramer's Rule, the solutions of equations (2.3) are 2 f. F*. i 1 ji . . 2 dxj/BP — - P-F* (1,3 — l,2,...,n) ( .5) where F31 is the cofactor of the j - 1 element in F*. We have seen that differentiation of the first-order conditions (1.4) with respect to pl resulted in 54 n jilfij axj/apl = l/P 511' (2.6) where 511 is the Kronecker delta. Further, the solutions to (2.6) are axj/apl = Fij/P-F*. (j = l,2,...,n) (2.7) Substitute equation (2.7) into definition (2.1): n f.-F*. _ jil 3 13 aQ/apl — P.F* . (2.8) Since P and F* are positive, we may conclude that input 1 is inferior if and only if n f.-F*. > o. 2.9 3 13 ( ) j 1 By using equation (2.5) in equation (2.8), we shall find dQ/dpl = - dxl/dP. (2.10) In words, the change in optimal output resulting from a change in the price of input 1 equals the negative of the change in the optimal usage of input 1 that results from a change in the commodity price. In the case of inferior inputs, the change in optimal output due to a change in pl is positive by definition. Consequently, the change in the quantity of X1 when commodity price changes is negative, i.e., 55 when commodity price increases, the quantity of input 1 employed decreases.4 3. An Alternate View of Inferior Inputs Equation (2.10) provides an equivalent definition of inferior inputs, viz., one whose use declines as commodity price, and hence output under perfect competition, increases. Consideration of this alternative makes the analogy between an inferior good in consumer demand theory and an inferior input in the theory of the firm easier to appreciate. But it will also point out that the analogy is not quite com— plete. .In the theory of consumer behavior, a commodity is inferior if the quantity demanded varies inversely with the consumer's income level. But the consumer is solving a constrained maximum problem. Thus changing his money income and re-computing his optimal expenditure pattern will reveal successive positions of equilibrium. In the theory of the firm, however, the firm deter- mines optimal inputs by solving an unconstrained maximum problem rather than a constrained maximum problem. Total cost is found by evaluating the cost equation after substi- tuting this vector of optimal inputs. The firm simply spends this amount in order to maximize profits. Although the firm's expansion path is analogous to the consumer's 4This section depended heavily upon work done by C. E. Ferguson in an unpublished manuscript. 56 income-consumption curve, the expansion path is not a locus of profit-maximizing points. But it is a locus of cost- minimization points and, therefore, every profit—maximizing point must also lie on the expansion path. Thus we can direct our attention to these specific profit-maximizing points for analytical purposes. But the slope of the expan- sion path can be examined for conceptual purposes. The firm's response to a demand led increase in i commodity price, ceteris paribus, is an expansion of output. Since the firm was in a profit-maximizing position before the price change, its iso-output surface was tangent to an iso-cost surface. To increase its output, the firm must move to a higher iso—cost surface. When one compares the two profit-maximizing positions in n-space, one will see that dxl/BC < 0 where C is total cost, i.e., the tangency of the new, higher iso-cost surface to the new, higher iso— output surface involves a diminished employment of the inferior input, x1. Thus the two concepts of inferiority are more closely related than the first definition of an inferior input might have indicated. 4. Inferior Inputs and the Level of Profits We have seen that an increase in the price of input 1 calls for an expansion of output when input 1 is inferior. But this expansion of output does not affect profits favor- ably. In fact, the increase in optimum output is accompanied 57 by a decrease in profits. This can readily be demonstrated by differentiating the profit function (1.3) with respect to pl: 5W _ . . ' _ 5p]. - is (P fi-pi) an/apl "" X1. (1 _ 1’2, ...,n) (4.1) From the first-order conditions, i.e., in equilibrium, the terms in parentheses are identically zero. Thus we have Since xl cannot be negative, - xl must be negative. There- fore, we may conclude that profit always varies inversely with input prices regardless of whether the input is infe- rior or not.5 5. Ipput Inferiority_and Restrictions on the Production Function Input inferiority places certain restrictions on the form that the production function can take. It can easily be shown that the production function cannot be homogeneous of degree one. To this end, suppose it is homogeneous of degree one. The bordered Hessian determinant of the produc- tion function is 5Bear proved this result in an elegant fashion. But he asserted that this proved that inputs could not be infe- rior at all levels of output because if they were, profits would vary directly with input price. Since he proved the opposite was the case in gay event, I find his argument rather unconvincing. 58 0 fl f2 ... fn fl £11 £12 ... fln f2 f12 f22 "' f2n F = . . . . . (5.1) fn fln f2n ... fnn As a matter of notation, number the rows and columns 0,1,2,...,n and let Fi represent the cofactor of the i—th element in column 0, Fij the cofactor of the i - j element in the body of F, and F the cofactor of the i - j element Oij in F0. Expansion of F1’ the cofactor of the 1 element in column 0 yields n F =->_‘,f.'F .. (5.2) l j=l j 013 But linear homogeneity of the production function implies n n 2 -'Zlfj Folj = (xl'F/Q )'21 j xj. (5.3) J: 3: Since Euler's Theorem applies, we may write (5.3) as n 2 n -j:lfj FOlj = (xlF/Q )jilfj xj = xlF/Q (5.4) Noting that x1, F, Q > 0, linear homogeneity implies f. F 13 n = Olj > 0. (5.5) 3 Inspection of F and F* reveals F0 = F* (5.6) 59 and FOlj - Flj' (5.7) Thus n n _j:lfj FOlj = -jilfj Flj' (5.8) Inequality (5.5) then implies that linear homogeneity requires n —j:1fj Flj > 0, (5.9) or n jilfj Flj < 0. (5.10) Therefore, by (2.9) linear homogeneity precludes input inferiority.6 Moreover, if the production function is such that an increase in any input increases the marginal products of all other inputs, input inferiority is also precluded. To demonstrate this proposition, suppose that the production function satisfies this condition and that input 1 is infe- rior. Differentiating the first-order conditions for a profit maximum (1.4) with respect to P yields [fij] [dxi/BP] = - l/P [fi] (i,j = l,2,...,n) (5.11) 6This point was mentioned as being obvious by Bear and was proved by Ferguson. 60 in matrix form. Under the hypothesis, fij2> o for i s j. (5.12) 3 Equation (5.11) may be solved by matrix methods It has been proven that all the elements of [fi ]-1 are negative. to obtain [dxi/BP] = - 1/p [fij]-l [fi]- (5.13) Since fi and P are positive, the right-hand side of (5.13) must be positive and this implies that dxi/BP > 0. (5.14) But substitution of (5.14) into (2.10) implies dQ/dpl < 0. (5.15) We clearly have a contradiction of definition (2.1). Thus a production function in which all marginal products are increasing functions of all other inputs effectively pre- cludes input inferiority.7 This result was proved by Bear, "Inferior Inputs . . .," p. 288. 61 6. Ipput Inferioripy and the Cross-Elasticipy of Input Demand We can derive the cross-elasticities of input demand functions from inequality (1.14) and relate this to the con- cept of inferior inputs. From the first-order conditions, fj = pj/P. Multiply both inequalities (1.14) by fj and sum over j: > . > l/P Z pj dxj/dpl < 0 according as 2 ijlj < O. (6.1) 3 j The proportion of total cost spent on input j can be expressed as . = . x. .x.. i = l,2,...,n 6.2 x] pJ J/i p1 l ( ) ( ) The price cross-elasticity of input demand between inputs i and j is defined as eij = axj/Bpi°pi/xj- (6.3) To introduce these definitions, multiply the left-hand inequality in (6.1) by ZPiXi '§; .9 (.4 Then condition (6.1) can be expressed as E3121 - z x. e . Z 0 according as 2 f. F*. 2 0- (6-4) P'pi j :1 13 j J 13 62 ZPiXi P-pi Since > 0, the weighted sum of the cross-elasticities of input demand is negative if input 1 is normal. But when input 1 is inferior, this sum will be positive.8 7. Inferior Inputs and Output and Substitution Effects So far, we have been dealing with a profit—maximizing in firm. This, of course, requires taking cognizance of total revenue. But prior to any revenue considerations, it is implicitly, if not explicitly, assumed that each competitive firm has chosen optimal quantities of inputs such that total output is maximized for each level of total cost, i.e., Q = f(xl,x2,...,xn) (7.1) is maximized subject to a given cost constraint 2 p.x. = E’ (i = l,2,...,n) (7.2) where it is still assumed that input prices are paramet—Q rically given by the market. To find these optimal input quantities, form the Lagrange expression L = f(Xl,X2, '001Xn) _7\(Z pixi - C)! (7'3) 8This entire section and the following section are mere adaptations or restatements of work done by Ferguson in his unpublished manuscript. 63 where A is an undetermined Lagrange multiplier. The first- order conditions are OL/dxi = f- " 7\P- = OI i i (7.4) aL/ax = z pixi - 6': 0. (i = l,2,...,n) i A regular relative maximum requires 2 n n d f = Z 2 f.. dx. dx. < 0 (7.5) i=lj=113 1 3 for n df =.z fi dxi = O, (7.6) i=1 where not all dxi are zero. This is equivalent to requiring the bordered Hessian determinant, 0 pl p2 "'p p1 f11 12 °°' fln f p f f ... D = 2 12 22 Zn ’ (7.7) pn f1n f2n "° fnn to have principal minors that alternate in sign, the first being positive. From the first-order conditions (7.4) Pi = fi/A- (1 = l,2,...,n) (7.8) Thus 64 0 f1 f2 ... fn f1 f11 f12 "' fln f f f ... f D = 1/12 2 12 22 2n = l/AZ F. (7.9) fn fln f2n "° fnn Since it can be shown that 1/1 represents marginal cost, l/x and consequently l/7\2 are positive. Thus Sign D = Sign F (7.10) and the signs of the corresponding principal minors of D and F must also be the same. Further, assuming that n is even renders the sign of F positive. In order to find the output and substitution effects, introduce a change in pl. The result may be expressed in matrix form: '0 pl p2 ... pn" "Lax/dplf 'in“ pl fll £12 ... f1n dxl/dpl A p2 £12 £22 ... f2n de/dpl = 0 (7 ll) pn fln f2n ... fnn dxn/dpl O The solutions to equations (7.11) may be found by using Cramer's Rule and (7.8): 2 "A X1 Fo + i F1 -OA/Opl = 4——ir———- F , (7.12) 65 and 2 2 -A x F. A F . _ l J 1:1 These solutions can be expressed in a more meaningful form by introducing the definition of the partial elasticity of substitution, .-=- l - —1-l ' (i,j = l,2,...,n) (7.14) and the identities F. = (-1)3 2: fk Fojk =(—1)3 >3 fk ng. (k=l,2,...,n) (7.15) 3 k k Using these in equations (7.12) and (7.13) reveals that —-A2>3 fk ka 12 x1 F* -aA/apl -— F - ——?———, (7.16) and Ale z fk Fik A2 x12 a"1/5‘31 = F + m 011 (7'17) 1 Because A and F are positive, dA/dpl Z 0 according as 2 fk ka + x1 F* 2 O. (7.18) If input 1 is inferior, z fk Flk is positive while xl-F* is also positive. But we know that A is the reciprocal of marginal cost. Thus marginal cost varies inversely with the price of input 1. Now it should be much easier to appreciate why the optimal output is higher when the price of an infe- rior input rises. One certainly should expect a firm to 66 increase its output when marginal cost falls. On the other hand, if input 1 were normal, Z:f *would be negative * kFlk while x -F* is again positive. But when the price of a 1 normal input rises, optimal output decreases. Therefore marginal cost must vary directly with pl. Hence xl-F* must be less than the absolute value of Z fk Flk' Because F is negative definite, F1 is negative when 1 n is even. Thus 011 is negative. The second term on the right-hand side of equation (7.17) may be called the substi- tution effect, which is clearly negative in all cases. This simply means that the quantity of input 1 demanded varies inversely with changes in input l's price when output is held constant. If input 1 is normal, the output effect, which is the first term on the right-hand side of (7.17), will also be negative. In this case of normal inputs, when input price changes both the output and the substitution effects operate to move quantity demanded in the opposite direction. _On the other hand, if input 1 is inferior, we shall have a positive output effect. Whether the total effect will result in an increase or decrease in the employment of input 1 depends upon the relative Sizes of the two effects. It is possible for dxl/dpl to be positive if the positive output effect is larger (in absolute value) than the nega— tive substitution effect. It must be emphasized that this does not imply that the slope of the firm's input demand 67 function is positive. We have seen in equations (1.11) and (1.12) that the slope of the true demand function is always negative regardless of the type of input considered. Yet we now find that Bxl/apl may be positive. This apparent incon- sistency can easily be resolved: in equation (7.17) we are 22E_considering an input demand function. The demand func— tions for inputs are derived from the profit maximizing conditions. Since revenue considerations never entered the calculations underlying (7.17), an input demand function cannot be derived from the calculus of maximizing output for given levels of total cost. CHAPTER IV THE INFLUENCE OF INFERIOR INPUTS UPON EXTERNALITY SOLUTIONS In the previous chapters, the concepts of external effects and inferior inputs were developed in some detail. We are now in a position to examine the effects of inferior inputs on the solutions to the resource misallocation prob- lem caused by externalities. As previously seen, an exter- nality in production is caused by one firm's use of an input having an effect on another firm's production function. When this situation is further complicated by the external- ity-causing input's being inferior, we Should like to know whether the remedies analyzed in Chapter II must be altered. In order to accomplish this, we shall pose a general problem of externality in which the input causing the trouble is inferior. The various solutions to the problem will then be examined to determine the influence, if any, of input infe— riority. Since the analysis will be conducted in partial equilibrium terms, it must be emphasized that the rest of the economy is, and remains, organized so that the Pareto optimum conditions are fulfilled. 68 69 l. The General Problem Suppose there are two firms, i and j, that produce according to the production functions: 0' = F(Xillxi21 °°°Ixinl Z), (1'1) and Q. = G(x. j jl'xj2’°'°’xjn)’ (1.2) where xik and xjk are the amounts of input k used by i and j respectively. We assume that these production functions are continuous and at least twice differentiable. The argument 2 in (1.1) is defined by z = g le-dG/dle - pl , (1.7) where Pi and Pj are product prices and p1 is the price of input le. This simply means that not only would i like to change j's use of input le, but that it is also possible for i to do so. A change is desirable because j's use of le has a deleterious effect on i's operations. Moreover, a change is possible because the damage done to i exceeds the net marginal benefit that j receives from its profit-maximizing usage of le. So long as inequality (1.7) holds, i.e., so long as the externality is Pareto relevant, there is a misallocation 1We must keep in mind that dF/dz = 5F/59(le)°d9(le)/dle. 71 of resources that prevents society from being on its trans— formation surface. Only by removing the Pareto relevance of the externality, i.e., by changing inequality (1.7) to lPi-dF/dz = l j as/ale - pl , (1.8) can society attain its transformation surface. We might note again that this does not require removal of the mar- ginal externality, but only the removal of its Pareto rele- , vance. Finally, assume that le is an inferior input. As we have seen, this requires n an/apl = : Gk axjk/apl > 0, (1.9) k l where Gk = dG/dxjk. By introducing this additional influ- ence into the externality problem, analysis of the solutions set out in Chapter II, "Solutions for the Externality Prob- lem," will reveal whether-any complications result.2 2. Solutions As in Chapter II, we shall only consider procedures that permit society to attain its transformation surface. In particular, we shall again examine the bargaining, 2We shall retain the assumptions made when we first dealt with these solutions, viz., the costs of adjustment are lump sum and the adjustment is worthwhile. See footnote 13 p. 21 for a discussion of these costs and assumptions. 72 tax-subsidy, and merger solutions under the additional influence of inferior inputs. Bargaining_ As in Chapter II, we must consider the legal pre- scription for liability as given and analyze the problem of external effects within this context. We shall begin with the case where the law prescribes no liability for j, the a. source of the externality, and then proceed to the case where j suffers full liability. No liability foryj.—-In this situation i is inter- ested in j's reducing the quantity of le employed. Because of the inequality in condition (1.7), i.e., because the external diseconomy is Pareto relevant, it is possible for i to induce j to decrease its use of le with a resultant mutual advantage. Since there is no legal restriction on j's actions, 1 must make a monetary appeal to j. Assuming that j's optimal use of le is 251, the presumption is that i will offer an amount B(§jl—le) to j.3 In other words, B is the side payment or bribe that 1 offers j per unit decrease in j's employment of le. Recall that le is the input that is directly related to z, the externality-causing by-product or condition, which enters i's production func- tion parametrically. 3Of course, no payment will occur if the term in parentheses is negative, i.e., if j increases its use of le. 73 The fact that le is inferior has no effect on 1 because i is merely interested in removing the deleterious influence that le creates. If the inferiority of le has any influence at all it will appear in j's response to i's offer. We can examine the profit function that j now attempts to maximize: n w. = P..G x. ,x. ,...,x. + B i1 -x. — x. . J 3 ( 31 32 3n) ( :11 31) kilpk 3k (2.1) The first-order conditions for a regular relative maximum are Pj-dG/dxjk - pk = 0 if xjk > O, (k = 2,3,...,n) (2.2) and Pj°dG/dle - (pl+B) = 0 if le > 0. (2.3) Since B > 0, 191 < (pl+B) . (2.4) Thus i's offer is equivalent to an increase in the price of le. This is what one should expect. The side payment from i to j is exactly equivalent, from j's point of view, to an increase in the market price of le. That is just to say,when externalities exist, some nonmarket mech- anism must accomplish what the market would otherwise do. Whether such a price increase will induce the desired change in j's employment of le is now the relevant question. 74 But the answer to this question has already been obtained in Chapter III, equation (1.11). There it was found that the quantity demanded of any input is inversely related to its price. This relation holds whether the input is inferior or not. Therefore, we may conclude that through an iterative procedure, the correct B can be found such that not only will equations (2.2) and (2.3) hold, but the first—order conditions for i will also be fulfilled, i.e., Pi-dF/dxik - pk = 0 if xik > 0, (k = l,2,...,n) (2.5) and _ 4 Pi-aF/az + B — o. (2.6) By solving equation (2.6) for B and substituting into (2.3), we shall find that the bargaining scheme will result in satisfaction of the requirement for Pareto opti— mality. Thus the inferiority of input le has no effect on the bargaining solution in regard to this policy for achiev- ing Pareto optimality when the law prescribes no liability for j's actions. But this inferiority does have an effect upon the resultant configuration of final prices and output. 4These first-order conditions follow from i's altered profit function: n ”1 = Pi°F(xil’xi2”°°’xin’z) - B(le—le) _k:1 pk Xik' 75 From equation (2.6), B = - Pi-dF/dz. (2.7) Substituting into (2.3) and rewriting yields Pj°dG/dle = pl - Pi-dF/dz. (2.8) Since dF/dz < 0 by condition (1.6), pj-ae/ale = pl + lpian/az . (2.9) Thus j must adjust its usage of le such that the value of le's marginal product exceeds its market price by the value of the damage done to i. In other words, when the side pay- ment or bribe is offered, the "effective market price" of le, from j's point of View, becomes pl + Pi'dF/dz . Firm j will then reduce its employment of le. Normally, reduc- ing le would cause a reduction of output and, if all entre— preneurs followed suit, the market price of commodity j would increase. But in the special case of le being an inferior input, output varies directly with the price of the input by definition. Thus the increase in the "effective market price" of le causes an expansion of j's output even though the employment of le is still reduced. Now, if all entrepreneurs follow suit, the market price of commodity j will fall. Full liability for j,--Now assume that the law prohibits j's imposing any externality upon 1 unless i is 76 willing to accept it. It is quite obvious that i will require some compensation in return for its permission to suffer the existence of 2. It is also quite obvious that A if le is the optimal quantity of le and /\ Pj°8G/8le - p1 > 0 for le < le, (2.10) j will find it profitable to compensate i for permission to use some positive amount of le. Suppose j offers 1 a bribe of B per unit of le for i's permission to employ le. Firm j's offer will change their profit functions to n Hi 2 Pi°F(Xil’Xi2"°"Xin’z) + B le -k§1 pk xik’ (2.11) and n w. = P.-G x. ,x. ,...,x. - B+ x. - x. . 2.12 3 j(3132 3n) (P1)31k§29k3k( ) Since these profit functions are essentially the same as those where no liability existed, we shall find that the first-order conditions are the same, i.e., Pj-dG/dxjk - pk = 0 if xjk > O, (k = 2,3,...,n) (2.13) Pj-oG/dle - (B+pl) = 0 1f le > 0, (2.14) Pi°8F/dxik — pk = 0 if xik > 0, (k = l,2,...,n) (2.15) and Pi°5F/dz + B = O. (2.16) 77 In light of the results (2.13) - (2.16), we can see that the effect of j's offer of a bribe is equivalent to an increase in the price of input le. Because we have shown that, 0 O irrespective of the type of input under consideration, an increase in input price causes a decrease in the quantity demanded, this legal arrangement will also lead to Pareto optimal input combinations. The direction of payment is reversed in this instance; but this is irrelevant to ques- tions of efficiency.5 Here again, however, the inferiority of input le will affect final prices and output. In order for j to employ le, j must make a side payment to i in addition to Paying the usual market price for the input. Thus the "effective market price" is increased from j's point of view. Of course, this results in j's decreasing its use of le below the level that would prevail in the absence of any legal liability. But, because le is inferior, output and input price vary directly. Therefore, the increase in the "effective market price" causes an expansion of j's output. Again, if all entrepreneurs follow suit, the market price of commodity j will fall. 5The intermediate case mentioned in Chapter II, "Bargaining," could also be analyzed as these polar cases have been. .Clearly, the result would be the same: Pareto optimality would ensue. 78 Taxes and Subsidies As we have seen, the tax-subsidy approach represents an alternative to the bargaining scheme.6 Since j's use of input le is causing the external diseconomy, this alterna- tive solution requires the levy of an appropriate tax on j's use of le and an equal subsidy payment to i. Although the result of this approach is fairly obvious, it is worth demonstrating. Let T represent both the tax on j's use of le and the subsidy to i. The profit functions of i and j now become n W1 — P.-F(xil,xi2,...,x.n,z) + ijl —k:lpk Xik’ (2.17) and n Wj = PjG(Xj1'Xj2’°'°’Xjn) - (T+Pl) le -kizpk Xjk' (2.18) Thus the first-order conditions are = 0 if x > 0, (k l,2,...,n) (2.19) Pi°5F/axik ‘ pk ik Pi-dF/dz + T = 0, (2.20) 2,3,...,n) (2.21) Pj-dG/dxjk - pk = 0 if xjk > 0, (k and pj-aG/ale — (T+pl) = 0 1f le > 0. (2.22) 6See Chapter II, "Taxes and Subsidies." 79 Equation (2.20) shows that the appropriate tax to be levied on j is one that equals the value of the damage done to 1. Clearly, these first-order conditions are identical to those obtained by private bargaining. If we solve equa- tion (2.20) for T and substitute into equation (2.22), we obtain pjoaG/ale - pll = lPi-dF/dzl, (2.23) i.e., we obtain the condition for Pareto equilibrium. Rearranging this equation to rj-aG/ale = pl + lPi-dF/dzl (2.24) shows that the effect of the tax is to induce j into equating the value of le's marginal product with the price of le plus the value of the damage its use does to i's operation. Again, input inferiority has no effect on this policy for achieving Pareto optimality because the price of le is raised by the tax, and this causes a decrease in the quan— tity of le demanded. But from equation (2.20L T = - Pi-dF/dz (2.25) Thus the tax and subsidy are precisely the same as the bribe or side payment in the bargaining case. As one might expect, the results will be the same: the increased "effective mar- ket price" of le will cause a reduction in the employment 80 of le and a consequent increase in j's output. As before, if all entrepreneurs follow suit, this will lead to a reduc- tion in the market price of commodity j. The result of taxing j's output when le is inferior can now be demonstrated.7 If, despite all objections by economists that taxing output will render j's choices for all inputs but le non-optimal, the government decides to tax output to remove the Pareto relevance of the external diseconomy caused by j's operation, the direct opposite of the desired result will occur when le is an inferior input. To demonstrate this, suppose a per unit tax t is levied on j's OUtPUt Qj' Firm j's profit function will then be n w. = P.°G x. ,x. ,...,x. - x. — t Q.. 2.26 J J (31 32 3n) k=lpk 3k 3 ( ) Because . = G x. ,x. ,...,x. , 2.27 Q3 (31 )2 3n) ( ) equation (2.26) can be re-written as n v. = P.-t 'G X. ,x. ,...,x. - z x. . 2.28 J (J ) (31 32 JH) k=lpk 3k ( ) Clearly, the effect of the per unit tax is to decrease the "effective market price" of j's output rather than to increase the "effective market price" of the input that causes the externality. We have seen in equation (2.10), Chapter III,that 7This was mentioned in Chapter II, "Taxes and Sub- sidies," without explanation. The result was demonstrated graphically by C. Plott in "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," Economica, XXXIII, 84-86. 81 de/dpl = - dle/dpj (2.29) in all cases. But the definition of input inferiority requires that de/dpl be positive. Thus expression (2.29) implies that the quantity of the inferior input le must vary inversely with commodity price. Since le causes the externality and the tax is supposed to remove this effect, we can now see the perverse result that Plott's graph demonstrated, viz., a tax on Qj' by decreasing its effective market price, causes j to increase its employment of le. This is obviously the opposite of the desired result. Mergers We can now turn to the third solution: merger of the firms involved. The effect of the merger will be to internalize the external diseconomy. This occurs because the new firm's profit function is n W = Vi + Wj = Pi-F(xil,xiz,...,xin,z) -k§1pk xik n (2.30) +P..G X. ,X. '00.,X. -2 X. o 3 ( 31 32 3n) kzlpk 3k The first-order conditions for profit maximization are k — 0 if xik > O, (k = l,2,...,n) (2.31) pk 0 1f xjk > 0, (k Pi-dF/dxik - p 2,3,...,rn (2.32) P.’8G dx. - J / 3k and Pi°dF/dz + Pj-dG/ale — p1 = 0 if le > 0. (2.33) 82 It is obvious that condition (2.33) can be rearranged to read lPi-dF/dz = le-dG/dle — pl , (2.34) which is the condition for Pareto equilibrium. While the other proper solutions involved raising the price of the externality-causing input, the merger solu- tion yields the desired result for a slightly different reason. The new, merged firm fully appreciates all the costs of employing le, i.e., the decrease in Oi for any given vector of inputs xil’xi2"°"xin as well as the price of le. Thus the optimal amount of le will be used. Since there are no longer any external effects, the fact that le is inferior can have no bearing on questions of Pareto optimality. However, as in the bargaining and tax-subsidy cases above, the fact that le is inferior leads to a differ- ent output configuration than would otherwise Obtain. 3. Conclusion In Chapter III, we saw the effects of input inferi- ority on the theory of production and the theory of derived demand. But in this chapter we found that input inferiority does not alter any of the solutions to the resource misallo- cation problem created by external effects. Since the possi- bility of the existence of inferior inputs cannot be ignored and their empirical Significance is quite difficult to 83 assess, this is a rather encouraging result. Moreover, since external effects cause enough complications by them- selves, it may be a blessing that inferior inputs do not further complicate matters. In the case of a non-inferior input, which is the cause of a Pareto relevant externality, full employment of all resources leaves society short of the transformation surface because the full utilization of the externality- causing input has a deleterious effect upon the operation of some firm or firms. When the Pareto relevance of the exter- nality is removed by bargaining, tax-subsidy manipulations, or internalization through merger, the offending firm employs less of the externality-causing input and conse- quently produces less output. The inputs released by the offending firm will then be employed by other firms whose usage of the inputs does not lead to external effects. This will expand their outputs and permit society to attain the transformation surface. But if the externality-causing input is inferior to j and non—inferior to other firms, the result is somewhat different. Removal of the externality's Pareto relevance through bargaining, tax-subsidy manipulations, or internal- ization will still cause the offending firm to decrease its usage of the inferior, externality-causing input; however, the firm's output will now increase as we have seen above. The released inputs will now be transferred to firms whose 84 usage of the inputs does not give rise to external effects. Since the externality—causing input is not inferior to these firms, their outputs will also increase. Thus, in this case, removal of the externality's Pareto relevance actually causes an outward shift of the transformation surface. APPENDIX A DERIVATION OF COST FUNCTIONS WITH EXTERNALITIES PRESENT While the term cost equation refers to cost expressed in terms of quantities of inputs and their respective prices, the term cost function denotes cost as a function of output. Cost functions can be used in the profit maximization problem by assuming that the firm employs optimum input combinations for all levels of output. Then the profit function becomes: W P-Q - f(Q) (A.l) where P is the product price, Q is the quantity of output, and f(Q) is the cost function. The first-order condition for profit maximization is now dW/dQ = P - df(Q)/dQ = 0. (A.2) Since df(Q)/dQ is obviously marginal cost, we have the usual condition for profit maximization: price equals marginal cost. The derivation of the cost functions, assuming the presence of an externality, can be revealing for our purposes. Therefore, I shall derive the cost function for a firm oper- ating in the presence of an externality under the assumptions 85 86 of (1) a Cobb-Douglas-type production function and (2) a CBS—type production function. Cobb-Douglas Let the production function be a b c Q = A X1 x2 2 (A.3) where xl,x2 are factors of production under i's control and z is the externality-causing output of j that enters i's production function parametrically. Differentiating the function partially with respect to the inputs yields the following marginal products: MP of X1 dQ/dxl = aQ/xl, (A.4) MP of x2 - dQ/dx2 bQ/x2, and MP of z = 50/52 = cQ/z. In accord with the definitions set out in Chapter II, "The Definition of Externality," we have an external diseconomy if dQ/dz < O which requires c < 0. On the other hand, c > 0 implies 80/82 > O, and we would have an external economy. Since the value of z is given parametrically, the necessary conditions for profit maximization are a°X2/b’xl = pl/pZI (A05) 87 where pl,p2 are the factor prices. Solving equation for x2 and substituting into equation (A.3) yields Q = A~kbozcoxi+b, where k = pl-b/pza. Then x1 = (Q/Akb.zc)l/a+b and similarly x2 = (Q/A.k-a.zc)l/a+b. (A.5) (A.6) (A.7) (A-B) Substituting these results into the cost equation gives us the cost function: b c)1/a+b C = pl.(Q/A.k .z C)l/a+b + pZ-(Q/A-k-a-z (A.9) An interesting point to note is that this cost function is not separable. Let us next consider a CBS—type production function. CBS-Type Let the production function be + a ~zd l/g. _ b b Q — A(al-xl + a2 x2 3 In this case, the marginal products are b—l Qal'b°xl /g(Z): MP of X1 dQ/dxl b-l MP of x2 — aQ/ax2 Q~a2-b'X2 /9(Z), (A.10) (A.11) 88 and \ d-l MP of z = oQ/dz = Q-a3-d-z /g(Z) where Z represents the term in parentheses in equation (A.10). .Again, if d,< 0, we have an external diseconomy: if d > 0, we have an external economy. Introducing z parametrically, we have as necessary conditions b—l b-l _ l.xl /a2.x2 — pl/pz. (A.12) a Solving (A.12) for X1 yields _ b-l 1/b-l xl - (pl.a2.x2 /p2.al) . (A.13) Substituting into equation (A.10) and letting W = (plaZ/p2a1)b/b'l, we have 0 = A(al.w.x§ + a2.x§ + a3-zd 1/9. (A.14) Then x2 = ((Q/A)g-a3°zd l/b (al-W+a2)-l/b (A.15) and similarly x1 = ((Q/A)g-a3'zd l/b - (al+a2-W-l)-l/b. (A.16) Now, substituting these results into the cost equation gives us the cost function: l/b l/b (Q/A)g - a3-zd (Q/A)g — a3 zd C : pl. 1 "l' p2“ ' (A'l7) a1 + a2-W al-W + a2 89 Note that in this case we also do not have separable cost functions. Further, we can see the effect of the external- ity in equations (A.4) and (A.11): the marginal products of the firm's own inputs are decreased in the diseconomy case and increased in the external economy case. An Example of a Separable Cost Function Let the production function be Q = x? + x; + ZB‘ (A.18) The marginal products are _ _ o-l MP of X1 — dQ/dxl — oxl , MP of x2 = aQ/ax2 = oxza-l, (A.19) MP of z = 80/82 = BZfi-l. If dQ/dz < 0, 2 causes a marginal external diseconomy. The necessary conditions for a profit maximum are x101-1 pl x d—l =-—- . (A.20) 2 p2 Solving (A.20) for X1 yields p x o—l l/d-l x = —l——3——— . (A.21) 1 p2 Substituting into the production function gives p x a-l a/o-l l 2 a 8 Q _ p2 + x2 + Z . (A.22) Thus 5 l/o +Z x2 = 479* o/o l , (A.23) (pl/p2) +1 and,similarly, B l/d x = 9+3 . l —1 l + (pZ/pl)a/a These values for X1 and x2 can be substituted into the cost equation to obtain the cost function: B 1/a B l/o C = pl + Zo/o—l + p2 g+0501-1 °(A’24) l + (92/91) (pl/p2) + 1 Since this cost function can be written as l/o l/o C=p Q? +p 25 l -l 1 -l 1 + (pz/pl)a/a . 1 + (pz/pl)a/a ( 25) A. l/d 1/d + P Q—T‘ + P 26 2 -1 2 -l ’ (pl/p2)“/“ +1 (pl/p2)a/a + 1 this cost function is separable. That this result occurs is apparent from the form the marginal products take, i.e., they are independent. It appears that so long as the exter— nality-causing input enters the production function in a purely additive way, the resultant cost function will be separable. APPENDIX B AN ALTERNATIVE VIEW OF THE EXTERNALITY—CAUSING INPUT I have been assuming that successive increases in 2 will cause increasing diminutions of output for i. The inclusion of z in i's production function makes it difficult to visualize the corresponding isoquants, or more correctly, the corresponding iso-surfaces. We may be able to gain greater insight by altering some of our concepts. First, let us consider i's production function: Qi = F(Xil'xi2"'°’xin’z)' (B.l) Note that I have replaced z with E'to indicate that j has decided upon its own optimum output and, therefore, upon the quantity of its inputs and, in particular, the quantity of le. Recall that z = g(le). When the production function has a specific form and a definite value is assigned to 2 we know the output possibilities that confront i. Any of these possibilities may be attained by employing certain quanti- ties of the n inputs. Naturally, the particular output and the corresponding vector of inputs decided upon will depend upon the price of the product and the prices of the inputs. The conceptual problem arises when we allow 2 to vary 91 92 because a positive 2 imposes a negative benefit on 1. Although it is natural for one to recognize that the xik l,2,...,n) represent positive changes from zero, it is (k somewhat unusual to think of E'as the origin for changes in z from i's point of view. But I am suggesting we do this so that firm i's production function becomes 12-2) 0 (B.2) All the constructs that were previously developed could easily be reworked in these terms. The advantage of using this formulation is that when i undertakes to change the value of 2, we can differentiate equation (B.2) with respect to -z. The marginal product of i's increased employ- ment of negative units of z is then positive. This altera- tion will render convex to the origin any isoquant's projec- tion onto the relevant plane in (n+l)-space. In a three— dimensional example, all we need do is label the axes correctly: y -Z 93 Note, in particular, the labeling of the —z axis and the definition of the z origin. Units of negative 2 are now "proper" inputs and the firm's iso-surfaces are concave from above. In addition, the assumption that increases in 2 yield increasing diminutions of i's output implies that the marginal productivity of negative units of z is decreasing, i.e., 82F/8(—z)2 < 0. It is now clear why we previously treated 2 as a nearly "normal" input: negative units of z are normal inputs. BIBLIOGRAPHY Allen, R. G. D. Mathematical Analysis for Economists. London: Macmillan & Co., Ltd., 1962. Bator, F. M. "The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization," American Economic Review, LXVII (March 1957) c 22-59- . "The Anatomy of Market Failure," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXII (August 1958), 351-79. Baumol, W. J. "External Economies and Second-Order Optimality Conditions," American Economic Review, LIV (June 1964), 358-72. Bear, D. V. T. "Inferior Inputs and the Theory of the Firm," The Journal of Political Economy, LXXIII (June 1965), 287-9. Buchanan, J. M., and Stubblebine, W. C. "Externality," Economica, N.S. XXIX (November 1962), 371-84. Buchanan, J. M., and Kafoglis, M. Z. "A Note on Public Goods Supply," American Economic Review, LIII (June 1963), 403-14. Buchanan, J. M. "Joint Supply, Externality and Optimality," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (November 1966), 404-15. Coase, R. H. "The Problem of Social Cost," The Journal of Law and Egpnomics, III (October 1960), 1-44. Davis, 0. A., and Whinston, A. B. "Externalities, Welfare, and the Theory of Games," Journal of Political Economy, LXX (June 1962), 241-62. Davis, 0. A., and Whinston, A. B. "welfare Economics and the Theory of Second Best," Review of Economic Studies, XXXII (January 1965), l-l4. Davis, 0. A., and Whinston, A. B. "Some Notes on Equating Private and Social Cost," Southern Economic Journal, XXXII (October 1965), 113-26. 94 95 Davis, 0. A., and Whinston, A. B. “On Externalities, Information, and the Government-Assisted Invisible Hand," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (August 1966), 303-18. Ferguson, C. E. Microeconomic Theory. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1966. . “Production, Prices, and the Theory of Jointly- Derived Input Demand Functions," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (November 1966), 454—61. "'Inferior Factors' and the Theories of Produc- tion and Input Demand," Economica, (to appear) May 1968. . Neo—Classical Theory of Production and Distribu- tion. (To be published.) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969. Hancock, Harris. Theory of Maxima and Minima. New Ybrk: Dover Publications, Inc., 1960. Henderson, James M., and Quandt, Richard E. Microeconomic Theory. New YOrk: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1958. Hicks, J. R. Value and Capital. 2d ed. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1962. Lerner, Abba P. The Economics of Control. New YOrk: The Macmillan Co., 1964. Liebhafsky, H. H. The Nature of Price Theory. Homewood: The Dorsey Press, Inc., 1963. Lipsey, R. G., and Lancaster, K. "The General Theory of Second Best," Review of Economic Studies, XXIV, No. l (1956), 11-32. Lloyd, Cliff. Microeconomic Analysis. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1967. Meade, J. E. Trade and Welfare (The Theory of International Economic Poligy, Vol. II). London: Oxford University Press, 1964. Mishan, E. J. "Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects," The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, XXXI (February 1965), 3-34 0 Musgrave, Richard A. The Theory of Public Finance. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1959. 96 Plott, C. R. "Externalities and Corrective Taxes," Economica, N.S. XXXIII (February 1966), 84-7. Reder, Melvin W. Studies in the Theory of Welfare Economics. New York: Columbia University Press, 1963. Russell, R. R. "A Graphical Proof of the Impossibility of a Positively Inclined Demand Curve for a Factor of Produc- tion," American Economic Review, LIV (September 1964), 726—32. Samuelson, P. A. "Prices of Factors and Goods in General Equilibrium," Review of Economic Studies, XXI, No. 1 (1953), 1-20. "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure," The Review of Economics and Statistics, XXXVI (November 1954), 387- 89. . "Diagrammatic Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure," The Review of Economics and Statistics, XXXVII (November 1955), 350—56. . "Social Indifference Curves," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXX (February 1956), 1-22. . "Aspects of Public Expenditure Theories," The Review of Economics and Statistics, XL (November 1958), 332- 38. Samuelson, Paul. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1963. Scitovsky, Tibor. Welfare and Competition. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1951. Turvey, R. "On Divergences between Social Cost and Private Cost," Economica, N.S. XXX (August 1963), 309-13. Vickrey, William. Microstatics. New York: Harcourt, Brace, & World, Inc., 1964. Wellisz, S. "On External Diseconomies and the Government- Assisted Invisible Hand," Economica, N.S. XXXI (November 1964), 345-62. ' Winch, D. M. "The Demand Curve for a Factor of Production: Comment," American Economic Review, LV (September 1965), 856-60.