PROBLEMS IN MEDIEVAL H!STORIOGRAPHY: A SELECTIVE STUDY Thesis for the Degree cf M. A. MECHKGAN STATE UNWERSITY Wayne Mitcheil Biedsce 196:5 THESIS LI BRA R Y Michigan Sm. University ABSTRACT Problems in Medieval Historiography: A Selective Study by Wayne M. Eledsoe Up to the nineteenth century there prevailed a certain point of view that colored every word written or Spoken about the early Middle Ages. Essentially, this period was viewed by the pre—nineteenth century writers as being a “dark age" stigmatized by the triumph of Christianity and barbarism. These writers saw coming with the fall of Rome in 476, a dark shadow that was cast over Western EurOpe leaving humanity to wander in ignorance and superstition until the veil of darkness was finally rent by the Renais- sance and Reformation of the fifteenth, sixteenth, and seventeenth centuries. This concept of the early Middle Ages as a "dark age“ received its original impetus from the writers of the Renaissance, Reformation, and Enlightenment periods. The Spokesman of these movements condemned the Middle Ages on the grounds that during this era men lost the ability to understand the Greek and Latin classics, corrupted the language, and sacrificed rational thinking for faith in the supernatural. These writers were content to label the Middle Wayne Mitchell Bledsoe Ages as a “dark age" and to remove it from the pages of history as being unworthy of consideration by future genera- tions. In reaction to those concepts which had been forced upon the Middle Ages, there arose in the nineteenth century a group of scholars who attempted to present the medieval' period in a greater qualitative light. The leaders of the Romanticist and Nationalist movements saw the Middle Ages not as a period engulfed by darkness, but as an age possessing a particular brilliance of its own. For the romanticists the Middle Ages represented a period when men expressed them— selves as they wanted. During this time the passions of men were allowed to run free. This particular school of thought could see a series of traits in medieval society that were never felt by the pre—nineteenthcnntury writers. The nationalist historians likewise viewed the Middle Ages as a period of many positive attributes. Being concerned primarily with the development of the national state, this school of writers found in the Middle Ages the origin of these states. They could see in this period primitive achievements which were later to evolve into full—fledged statehood. Thus, these scholars saw existing in the Middle Ages a series of traits and values which led not to a condemnation of the period but praise. This was an age when the future states of EurOpe were being formulated and when man eXpressed himself in a care free manner. Wayne Mitchell Bledsoe This conflictcf opinion which has been briefly sketched here concerning the nature and importance of the Middle Ages, is essentially the basic problem with which this present work will deal. This problem will be approached by offering a comparative study of those sources which have been influential in shaping medieval thought over the past three centuries. In essence, this work is not intended to present a new or unique thesis concerning the Middle Ages, but its value and usefulness lies within the fact that it brings together and offers a synthesis of those theses which have been essential in the development of Medieval history. While the nineteenth century was responsible for beginning the task of rediscovering the Middle Ages, which the previous centuries had dismissed as useless, the greatest adhievements in lighting this “dark age" have been made in recent decades. With the increase in number and ability of specialized scholars studying the various aSpects of the classical and medieval civilizations, it is no longer possible to support many of the views tenaciously accepted by pre- nineteenth century scholars. For example, it is no longer plausible to accept the belief that the beginning of the Middle Ages was a “catastrophic“ event heralded by the triumph of Christianity and barbarism. but rather, as modern research has indicated, it was an evolutionary process with the dates of its genesis varying with the consideration of each particular institution. Along with the study of classical Wayne Mitchell Bledsoe and medieval institutions which resulted in the diSproval of the catastrophic theses, went the invalidation of those beliefs which held the Middle Ages to be a dark age contain- ing little of value for the modern world. It is now generally accepted from the work of modern medievalists that this was a vital period best characterized as a period of incubation. It was out of the chaos following the fall of Rome that there emerged in the Western portion of the Roman Empire a dis- tinctively different way of life from which the greater and more enlightened Western European civilization was to emerge. Just as modern research has pointed out, the true significance of the Middle Ages is not that it marked the end of classical civilization, but that it represented the beginning of a new way of life that was later to blossom into the Western European civilization. Thus, the major end sought by this work is to prove by a comparative study of essential medieval theses that the true significance of the Middle Ages is that it served as the incubation period for Western European civilization. PROBLEMS IN MEDIEVAL HISTORICGRAPHY: A SELECTIVE STUDY by Wayne Mitchell Bledsoe A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTERS OF ARTS Department of History 1965 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page PREFACE 0.0....0.0.0.....OOOOOOOOO0.0000000000000000. ii CHAPTER I. The Beginning of the Middle Ages: Catastrophic or Transitional? .,.......... 1 II. Political Transition (3rd-6th Centuries).... 23 III. Economic Transition (3rd-6th Centuries) .... 39 IV. Social Transition (3rd-6th Centuries) ...... 56 V. Cultural Transition (3rd-6th Centuries)..... 70 VI. The Merovingian and Carolingian Dynasties: Progression or Retrogression? ............lOl VII. The Rise of the Moslem Empire and Its Significance .QOOOOOOOCDCOOOOOOQO00...... 136 mbICI‘USIOlq OCOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.000.000.0000000000 152 BIBLIOGRPEPHICEKL ESSAY ooooooooooooooooooooo0.00....- 155 Preface One of the greatest problems confronting any historian is that of persuading his audience to view a particular period of the past without preconceived notions. This is an old story in the study of history and one that is as sad as it is old. Probably no other period in history has been so burdened with this task as has the Middle Ages. DeSpite the efforts of medievalists in recent decades to undo the false conceptions wrought by earlier scholars wearing glasses of various colors, many educated persons still persist in accept- ing those ideas and beliefs that are no longer tenable. For this reason, one of the objectives of this work will be to examine the past three centuries of medieval historiography in an attempt to reconstruct some of these fallacious beliefs and in the process illustrate the efforts of modern scholars to combat them. Naturally to present a definitive study of all the sources embodied in this vast span of years would be an impossible task. Thus, of necessity, the present work will deal with those sources which most adequately represent their reSpective periods while at the same time illustrating the development made in historiography. Many of the historiographical problems that have arisen over the centuries have been created by the conflicts ii of opinion concerning the beginning of the Middle Ages. Was this a “catastrophic“ event hemalded by the onslaught of Christianity, or was it an "evolutionary" process covering over two centuries of decay and devastation within classical civilization? Did the beginning of the Middle Ages mark the introduction of a "dark age" that was for centuries to engulf Western Europe, or was it the genesis of a new civilization that was soon to surpass even the golden-age of Rome? So significant have these two questions been in the development of medieval historiography that a second objective of this work will be to establish whether or not the beginning of the Middle Ages was a catastrOphic event and if it was the beginning of a "dark age“ containing little of value for the modern mind. ‘ More Specifically, our task will involve a consider- ation of when and under what circumstances the ancient world came to an end in Western EurOpe and the medieval began. In considering this problem, it will be necessary to examine the various institutions of the ancient and medieval world in an attempt to establish how and when the classical order became medieval. The method by which this problem will be approached is not intended to be a chronological history of the early Middle Ages, but rather a comparative study of those sources which have been essential in shaping medieval scholarship. By employing such an approach as this not only will it be possible to see the development being made by medievalists, but also to clear away some of the acadenic debris that is no longer tenable and serves only to obscure the study of iii Medieval history. This will enable us to accomplish the last objective of this work, that of establishing the true significance of the epoch making era, the early Middle Ages. The process of research and writing always gives rise to many unrepayable debts. I would eSpecially like to acknowledge my indebtedness and eXpress my gratitude to Professor Ridhard E. Sullivan for his professional guidance, personal interest, and constant encouragenent which were so essential in the preparation of this manuscript. Also, Special recognition must go to my wife, Marilyn Joyce, whose assistance and encouragement will always be unrepayable. Wayne Mitchell Bledsoe Michigan State University July, 1965 iv Chapter I THE BEGINNING OF THE MIDDLE AGES: CATASTROPHIC OR TRANSITIONAL? Within the shadows which marked the waning of the seventeenth century, the new seeds of science which had been sown thnough the investigations of such men as Descartes and Bacon, began to germinate and burst forth into full life in the eighteenth century movement known as the “Enlightenment.“1 Being strongly influenced by these scientificarhievements the scholars of this, the “Age of Reason“, began to apply those experimental and inductive methods, by which science was achieving its conquests, to such areas as ethics, politics, religion, and economics. With the new sun of reason beaming in the heavens of the rationalist, he would no longer accept anything whidh could not be supported by the trestle of rational thinking. When this scientific concept of historical investiga- tion is applied to the early Middle Ages, it is obvious that the period which witnessed such events as the triumph of Christianity and barbarism, will not be Spoken of in very amiable terms. One of the personalities of this age whose 1J. B. Black, The Art of History, (New York, 1926) p. 22. 2 writings contributed immensely to the darkening of the Middle Ages was the master mind and founder of the Rationalist school, the intrepid genius, Voltaire. Also listed among the rationalist numbers is the prolific and polished historian Edward Gibbon, whose Dggline and Fall of the Roman Empire, S along with Voltaire's voluminous work mirrors most exquisitely this buoyant faith in science and reason. While most rationalist writers saturate their work with the intellectual and philoSOphical problems in the development of humanity, Gibbon's work could best be described as a literary epic. Using the pristine or golden age of Rome as an absolute standard2 against which all others are to be judged, he saw flowing with the wave of barbarians which engulfed Western Europe, the prOSpects of misery and desola- tion which would plague Europe for the next thousand years.3 The country was exhausted by famine, pestilence, and war. To view the irretrievable ruin of populous districts which had once been adorned with flourishing cities, was a deplor- able and painful sight.4 Although the material losses were greatly abhorred by the inhabitants, their most excruciating loss was that of 2Edward Gibbon, The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman EmpireI ed. J. B. Bury, 5th ed., Vol. I (London, 1923), p. 78. .BGibbon, IV, p. 55. 4Ibid. 3 personal liberty.5 Under the decaying rule of the Merovingians personal servitude and slavery were not only revived, but multiplied.6 Paralleling their loss of indivi- dual liberty, the Romans found themselves exposed to the laws of the barbarians, which in comparison to the Roman legal code, revealed a colossal deficiency in humanity and justice.7 The empire had communicated to the barbarian its language, law, and religion, only to find all in an unpalatable state of degradation and its citizens in personal servitude. Voltaire, who looked upon human history as having been carried along chiefly by the clash of ideas and civiliza- tions, is most adequately classified as an intellectual historian. While it is a laudable task, in the eyes of Voltaire, to record those ideas which advanced humanity or rendered greater happiness, it is also reasonable to ignore those whiCh serve only to burden the memory. Thus, if silence is significant, Voltaire projects a most unique and profound criticism of the early Middle.Ages. His treatment of this period receives no stationary position in the chrono— logical development of his history and that which can be ascertained is only fragmentary and piecemeal until the reign of Charlamagne when the story develOps a more concrete sIbid., p. 56. Ibid., p. 132. 7Ibid., p. 123. form. Voltaire's mode of approach to the barbarians appears to be a twin to Gibbon's. With the onslaught of barbarians, Western Europe was submerged in a state of profound devasta- tion, inhumane poverty, and gross ignorance.9 The only portrait which can be portrayed on the canvass of history of this vagrant mass is one of beastly tribes standing in 10 These dire need of being subdued by a civilized nation. conquerors subsisted upon rapine and theft while about them lay fallow vast regions of rich, fertile soil. They destroyed and ravaged numerous cities while founding none to replace them.11 In short, the barbarians brought ruin and decay to all that they touched, while contributing nothing to the development of humanity. In common with all the rationalists of the period, Gibbon and Voltaire disdained the triumph of Christianity because, as they contended, it was a superstitious growth fostered in a barbaric age and productive of fanaticism. Gibbon sees Christianity as being the prime factor which ____.._ 8Voltaire, The Works of Vgltaire, "General History“ (New York, 1901), XXIV. (Evidence of Voltaire's attitude con- cerning the early Middle Ages can be seen in his chapter head- ings as he passes from the fall of Rome to the age of Charlamagne as if nothing of value occurred during the four centuries that separated these two periods). 91bid., p. 6. lllbid., p. 111. 5 brought chaos to the social, political and military institu- tions of the empire, when they most desperately needed 12 orderly operations. With this weakening and undermining of the greatest civilization previously known to mankind, he could not avoid being antagonistic toward Christianity.l3 Yet he does pay tribute to its cohesive and sustaining powers, once the secular empire had disintegrated. If the decline of the Roman Empire was hastened by the triumph of Christianity, the victorious religion broke the violence of the fall as it mollified the ferocious temper of the conquerors and im- parted unto them such virtues as justice and mercy.14 Voltaire's very articulate hostility for religion can best be explained by his profound disapproval of what he considered to be misbehaviour of the clergy. Christianity, which evolved from very humble origins, had been subjected to all manner of corruption, secretions and superstitions by the ingenius and ambitious clergyman for their own selfish ends. The results of such degrading behavior left the one institution that was intended to be the great binding force in the world as a prime source of devastation, destruction, 15 and death. These men had taken the newly formulated dogma 12Gibbon, IV, p. 163. 13Gibbon, III, p. 324. 14Gibbon, IV, pp. 79, so, 163. 15Voltaire, XXIV, pp. 85-87. 6 and used it as an instrument, supported by mysterious rites, to control the minds of the ignorant. Under this influence man lent himself to intolerance, persecution, burnings, and 16 As a result of murders: all in the name of religion. religion possessing man's mind with a capricious medley of cunning and simplicity, of brutality and artifice, the early Middle Ages is an era deeply scarred by decay, superstition and ignorance. In conclusion it follows logically that Voltaire and Gibbon could not eXpress themselves temperately or as un- interested Spectators on this subject and as a result the positive side of these facts, strictly Speaking, were not called to their attention. They failed to see the new prin- ciples of life and energy imparted to the world by the bar- barians, and particularly by the Church. In virtue of their theme they could not do justice to the growth of the papal monarchy and the ecclessiastical organization of Eunope, which sprang from the ashes of this decadent world, becoming in the course of centuries the nucleus of a new and more en— lightened order. For Gibbon and Voltaire the course of European history in the Middle Ages is a "trough“ in the develOpment of humanity: it is truly a dark age. As the eighteenth century passed away so did the approach used by the Enlightenment scholars which presented 162mm. , p. 96. 7 the Middle Ages as a dark period in the Span of history. With the beginning of the nineteenth century there arose in re- action to the Enlightenment a school of thought known as the “Romantic School,“ whose purpose it was to present the Middle Ages in a much greater qualitative manner.l7 Being motivated by a desire to trace the develOpment of the national state, the romanticist viewed the Middle Ages as a period when man eXpressed himself as he wanted. He let his passions express themselves in a free manner. This particular school of thought saw a series of traits and attributes existing in the medieval man that were never realized by the writers of the Enlightenment period. Although the endeavors of this school were often saturated with an emotional appeal aimed at combatting the blighting theses of the eighteenth century, their work did serve to illuminate some of the darkened corners of the Middle Ages. Until the romanticist came to the front, the Middle Ages were actually as a sealed book with such men as Voltaire proclaiming, "the period deserves as little study as the doing of wolves and bears,“ and Gibbon's contempt for religion rendering him blind to the significance of the prin- ciple objects which he passed in the course of his journey.18 l7Harry Elmer Barnes, A Historyyof Historical Writing, (Norman 1938), p. 207. 18G. P. Gooch, History and Historiaps, (New‘York, 1913), p. 11. 8 A most adequate representative of the nineteenth century philOSOphy is the sympathetic and patriotic expounder of French history, Jules Midhelet. Looking at his work, Ehg History of France, which is in itself a small library, we see the barbarians whiCh embody the pages of his work are presented in a much greater qualitative nature than the repugnant picture of “the beast devouring the lamb“ painted by the rationalists. “Can it not be said that in the Germanic successes over the empire, this revealed not a negative quality, but it illustrates that personal devotion and submission to order which have in every age been 19 characteristic of these people.“- These qualities Simply reveal the Sign of the eminently social, docile, and flex- ible genius of the Germanic races.20 These first major invasions of the Empire in 39S A.D. cannot accurately be described as a season of degradation, because the barbarians had long been quartered in the prov- inces of the empire and had absorbed much of their civilizing attributes. The land which they took was that which had al- ready been removed from cultivation, and it was not uncommon for the invader to indemnify the landowners for his lost 21 land. It is true, as Michelet points out the warlike ngules Michelet, History of France, I, (New York, 1951), p.78. 9 heirarchy which governed the behavior of the barbarians, that this age stood below the civil order of past ages. How- ever, this is not to suggest that this age can be dismissed as a “dark age", contributing nothing to the develOpment of humanity, as the rationalists would have it. As Michelet has indicated in his work, it was during this period that the foundation was established for those institutions that were later to evolve into the much more enlightened age of the National State. During the early Middle Ages when the political, social, and military institutions were floundering in the state of stagnation, it was the Church which retrieved the fallen reins of progression and guided the embryonic state 22 While the ”genius of the to a more solid foundation. barbarians,“ which is a phrase coined by the romanticists to explain those early developments which they could in no other way eXplain, was being transformed into a usable and civil instrument, it was the Church which served as guardian of the West and guided the develOpment into its most advant- ageous form.23 Everything began to favor the absorption of society by the Church. Romans and barbarians, slaves and freemen, man and land, all flocked to her and took refuge in 24 her maternal bosom. When the Church began to suffer 22 Ibid., pp. 64, 65. 23Michelet, I, pp. 99, 100. 24 Ibid., p. 101. 10 ill-effects from her too frequent contact with the barbarian world she was able to find refuge in the shelter of monasti- cism. The monastery served as an asylum for the Church just as the Church had served society, while western EurOpe was 25 The forging her way through this period of transition. Church had taught the barbarians to bow their nedks to the yoke of civilization and Christianity. The early Middle Ages is thus the foundation for a greater, more prosperous, and more enlightened order which is to come. As the nineteenth-century was drawing to a close, scholars were still concerned with the develOpment of the national state, but their mode of approach had been greatly altered by develOpments in other areas of research. No longer were they dominated by the emotional appeal of the Romanticists, but were now motivated by a more scientific out- look. With the appearance in 1894 of W. E. H. Lecky's, History of Eurgpean Moralg, we see a conscientious effort being made to apply the biological concepts of evolution to the realm of social change. His writing is illustrative of the cultural and historical implications of the evolutionary notions.26 The major significance of Lecky's work is that it represents one of the first efforts to broaden history by penetrating behind the scenes of action.27 zslbid. 26Harry Elmer Barnes, A History of Historical Writing (Norman, 1938), p. 332. 27G. P. Gooch, History and Historians,(New York, 1913), p. 366. 11 Professor Lecky's entire thesis is based upon the debatable hypothesis that moral standards are in a constant state of progression.28 From the reign of Constantine, when Christianity was first adopted as the accepted religion of the Empire, it began to exert a powerful influence upon the moral standards of the inhabitants whiCh eventually brought about a series of changes resulting in the formation of those institutions, such as feudalism, which served as the direct forerunner of the national state. Although the Church itself may have been corrupted during this process, it did not hinder the evolution or moral development that was tak- ing place within society. The first stages of Leeky's evolutionary process sees the Church project on the pages of history as a very philantropic institution, imparting to its subjects a new sense of the sanctity of life and deve10ping a much needed concept of universal brotherhood.29 As long as the moral life of the Empire had been directed by the teaChings of pagan religions there existed no knowledge of the true value of human life. Man had never ascertained from nature that it was wrong to slay, without provocation, his fellowman, as can be seen in the gladiatorial games of the day. Christianity dogmatically asserted the sinfulness of destroying human life for amusement and imparted to the 28James J. Auchmuty, Lecky, (London, 1945), p. 50. 29William Edward Hartpole Lecky, History of Eur0pean Morals, (New York, 1894), p. 18. 12 Empire a moral standard higher than any which then existed in the world.30 This new'moral code encouraged the subjects of the Empire to develOp hOSpitals for the increasing number of orphans: discouraged the common practice of infanticide: and altered the severe penal code.31 With the increasing strength of the Church within society there also arose a more humane law regulating the treatment of slaves. Al— though slavery was to persist until the fourteenth-century the slave-master relation became more liberal when the Churdh began to exercise its power of exclusion from com- munion to tyrannical masters. While this first stage of Christianity came to be looked upon with adoration there soon arose a great ascetic movement which eventually diverted the enthusiasm of the Church into new channels. Emphasis was no longer placed upon the virtue of charity, but now passed to the newly ac- centuated Chastity. Although this was to curb the outward works and material accomplishments of the Church, it did not hinder the moral development. As the ascetic movement was evolving through its embryonic stages of development, that which was finally accepted by the West, under the masterful influence of St. Benedict, assumed a nature free of the hermetical deprivations 3OIbid., p. 20. 3lIbid., pp. 27—43. l3 exercised in the East and as a result became more accept- able to the EurOpeans who, for climatic reasons, were less capable of performing sudh rigid ascetic feats.32 It was this institution which was to serve as the sole center of civilization during the chaotic period of the Germanic invasions in the fifth century. The monastery assumed the social, political and intellectual functions of the West.33 While the author believes it is possible to criticize many of the policies of the Church during this period, such as its inserting the fear of hell and demons into the mind of EurOpe, at the same time the establishment of the monk as the idol of society had a profound effect upon the moral development of Europe. As men sought refuge in the monastic haven their attitude toward such essential issues as labor was greatly altered. No longer was this looked upon as a task for slaves, but became a virtuous occupation for all men. Also, the monastery was responsible for inserting in- to society the virtues of passive obedience and humility whiCh provided the foundation for the later acceptance of feudalism. All of these develOpments arose out of the chaos following the fall of Rome and were intimately related to 32Cuthbert Butler, Benedictine Monarchism, (London, 1962). Butler has a very interesting work which deals with the evolution of the monastic movement and its effect upon Western Europe. 33Lecky, p. 179. 14 the Church. It was in this manner that a particular atti- tude was gradually acquired that assimilated with the monarchical and aristocratic institution of feudalism, whiCh later flourished because they correSponded with the moral feeling of the time. As these virtues of obedience and humility suffi- ciently saturated the moral fibers of society, and as the barbarian kings became more settled, the idol of society was eventually changed from the monk to a royal sovereign which can be illustrated, par excellence, by the reign of Charlamagne.34 Although the institution of feudalism was not yet fully develOped it was being formulated and with it the foundation of Western Europe was being laid, primarily as a result of the moral evolution which prepared the minds of Europe for such a change. Although the nineteenth-century writers were success ful in lighting some of the darkened corners of the Middle Ages, there still did not exist an adequate coverage of the true significance of the period. The romanticists of the nineteenth-century were primarily too emotional in their efforts to counteract the biased attacks of the Enlighten- ment to present an objective study of the age and the later scholars of the century, while overcoming this passionate approach and being more scientific in their study, were 34Ibid., p. 271. lS primarily concerned with the genesis of the national state, therefore, leaving much of the early Middle Ages still un- toudhed. Thus, we can see that up to the twentieth-century there prevailed particular points of view that colored every word that was spoken or written concerning the early Middle Ages. The eighteenth—century scholars of the Enlightenment, being motivated by their newly formulated "Age of Reason", continued to present this vast Span of years as a dark age deserving not one moment of study from their intellectually brightened day. Then came the romanticists reaction to the Enlightenment which served to present the Middle Ages in a better light, but still did not adequately examine the period as a whole. As the nationalist historians adopted a more scientific approach and tried to weigh each period of history equally, they were able to bring forth in a brief period sufficient evidence to Show the Middle Ages were not a dark age, however, even they were not as impartial as they would liked to have been and as a result they became pri- marily concerned with the origin of the national state which led them to neglect the early Middle Age. We have then, with the beginning of the twentieth-century, one seg- ment of the Middle Ages, that period from the fall of Rome to the Caroligian age, remaining in darkness. Since Wbrld War I, many reputations have been made by men who assumed the task of lighting this remaining dark age, and it is with these scholars and their work that the major part of this paper will be concerned. 16 To force re-examination of long established ways of historical thinking requires both powerful and original minds, and fortunately the twentieth-century possessed many such men. But if there was any one man who upset the tran» quility of the historians world, it was Henri Pirenne, the celebrated national historian of Belgium. Breaking with the encyclopedic character of past interpretation, which was concerned primarily with the political and religious ques- tions of the Middle Ages, Pirenne began to ask new questions bringing new life to the nature of the past and in the pro- cess yielding greater knowledge and leading to new under- standing. One of the essential problems which must be solved in the course of our journey is that of the transition from the ancient world to medieval civilization. The artificial periodization of an Ancient world, the Middle Ages, and the Modern times is no longer adequate for the historians task, in that it denies the essential continuity of human eXperi- ence. Prior to the twentieth-century it had become general- ly accepted that the "Ancient world" and the "Middle Ages” were easily distinguished the one from the other and that a distinct break came in the fifth-century with the disappear- ance of the Roman emperor in the West, the appearance of the Germanic "barbarian“ kingdoms, and the triumph of Christianity.35 35Voltaire, The Works of Voltairg, "Annals of the Empire,“ pp. 7,8, Edward Gibbon, The Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, Vol. VII, p.308. "In these volumes, I have described the triumph of barbarism and religion": Jules Michelet, History of France, "The national language and religion...Slumbered under Roman culture until the advent of Christianity," p. 62. 17 This “catastrOphic“ interpretation became the textbook point of view and, with some qualification, a controlling assumption of scholars as well. From Pirenne's investigations, a radically different concept emerged to the forefront. AdOpting what could rightfully be classified as a “modified" catastrOphic thesis, he concluded that the Roman world — economically, culturally, and even in essence politically — continued in all parti— culars through the centuries of the German invasions. It was rather the impact of Islam in the seventh and eighth- centuries which, by destroying the unity of the Mediterranean, ended the Roman world and led to a strikingly different ’ civilization in the Carolingian age.36 We can see the critical era in the Pirenne thesis was no longer the fifth- century Germanic invasion, but the seventh and eighth- centuries which witnessed the triumphant entry of the sons of the Arabian desert, which brought an end to the heretofore classical unity. ‘ However, the catastrOphic thesis had already been seriously challenged before the appearance of M. Pirenne's Mohammed and Charlamagpe by the distinguished Austrian scholar, Alfons Dopsch, in his classic, The Economic and Social Foundations of European Civilization, which appeared in 1923-24. Professor DOpsch holds that the famous "fall" 36Henri Pirenne, Medieval Cities, (Garden City, 1926), p.27: Mohammed and Charlamagngy (New York, 1939), p. 293. 18 of the Roman Empire in the West was by no means the catas- trophic overthrow of an advanced civilization by the primi- tive German barbarians. On the contrary, medieval civiliza— tion descends in an orderly evolutionary fashion from that of the late Roman Empire. In fact, the Roman world was won by the Germans gradually from within, by a peaceful penetra- tion which went on for centuries during which they absorbed its culture and even, to a considerable extent, took over 37 “Rome did not fall in 476: it fell "38 its administration. asleep without any convulsion. The attitude of the Germans to Roman organization, as conquerors after the fall of Roman rule, was conservative in their own interest, and they continued to develOp their ridh inheritance. Thus, Dopsch's emphasis is upon the “continuity“ of this civilization and not disruption of those institutions which the Germans had so richly inherited. Additional weight was added to the growing accep- tance of a “transitional thesis”, as opposed to the long accepted catastrOphic view, with the publication in 1927, of Ferdinand Lot's, The End of the Ancient world and th§_ Beginning of the Middle Ages. While Pirenne saw no major 37Alfons Dopsch, Economic and Social Foundations of Egropean CivilizatiogL (New York, 1937), p. 386. 8 3 Ibid., p. 386. 19 break in the dike of classical civilization until the seventh and eighth-centuries, and Dopsch not even then, Ferdinand Lot. digresses to the second-century in citing the critical period of the Empire's existence. It was not ex- ternal forces which brought Roman civilization to its knees, it was above all an internal disease that undermined it and brought "the dissolution of all its vital forces," which condemned it to death.39 Within the second-century there were fatal maladies which reached their zenith during the third-century and in the process heralded the entrance of the Middle Ages. While the details of these maladies which plagued the Empire will not be discussed until later chapters, it is evident that Lot would essentially argue that the Germanic invasions did not represent an epoch mak- ing episode in that the transition from ancient to medieval civilization was in the making before the barbarians ex— posed themselves as a serious threat. The noted Catholic historian, Christopher Dawson, places such Significance upon these internal maladies plaguing Rome as to suggest antiquity would have eXperienced the same end had the barbarians never appeared on the scene.40 Still another attempt was made to bridge the great gulf whidh separates the ancient and medieval worlds by 39Ferdinand Lot, The End of the Ancient world and the Beginning of the Middle AggsL (New York, 1931), p.84. 4OChristOpher Dawson, The Making_of EurOpe (New York, 1932), p. 84. 20 H. St. L. B. Moss in his work, The Birth of the Middle Ages, which appeared in 1935. While we have already seen various dates ranging from the third to the eighth century as the beginning of the Middle Ages, and each having its justifica- tion according to the importance attached to a particular aspect of European civilization, Professor Moss cites the year 395 A.D. as having as good as claim as any to be regarded in this light, for the death of Theodosius the Great in this year occurred at a moment most critical for EurOpe. For the past three years Theodosius had ruled supreme over Roman territory. Henceforth, there is to be a separation of East and West coupled with a gradual dismemberment of the Western provinces. One change, however, of greater importance than any other for the future of Europe, was introduced by Constantine, when the Christian Church was admitted to share in the government of the State. Only under Theodosius does the Roman Empire finally cease to hold the balance between Christian and Pagan. For this reason, if for no other, 395 can be accepted as the beginning of the Middle Ages in that it herald the founding of the Christian State. Of the more recent scholarship, William C. Bark's ggigin of the Medieval World serves as an adequate represent- ative. Bark sets no Specific dates for the end of the ancient world and the beginning of the Middle Ages, but does believe the critical period to have been the civil strife of the third century. Although there were extensive 21 efforts at recovery from those internal problems, by the end of the fourthrcentury the Middle Ages had begun. The collapse of the West as a centrally administrated part of the Roman Empire took place before the great barbaric victories. "The Western Empire ceased to exist when it proved incapable of resisting small bands of barbaric tribes— men.”41 No date is given for this event because it was an evolution, reaching its culmination at different times with different institutions. The final breakdown simply represents the end of an experiment which had failed and this left the way Open for a new eXperiment possessing new creative force.42 While it is reserved for the remaining chapters of this work to discuss the details and examine the variations of these twentieth century theses, it is obvious from the "variety" of dates given for the beginning of the Middle Ages that the loosely constructed catastrophic thesis is no longer plausible as a starting point for the Middle Ages. It is a matter now, not of one date but many dates, each involving the development of a particular phase of medieval civilization. No longer can the scholar be content to ex— amine only the political and religious institutions, as did many of the eighteenth and nineteenth—century writers, but 41William Carroll Bark, Origins of the Medieval world, (Stanford, 1958). p. 66. 421bid., p. 39. 22 now his sights must be broadened to include the economic, social and cultural transitions as well. “Half a century ago, George Burton Adams, then the Dean of American Medievalists, ... observed that the history of Europe... had been so minutely investigated that on all important questions in this field there is now a nearly or quite general consensus of Opinion among scholars."43 Fortunately, however, the consensus has been proven to be not so general by the extensive Specialized research of twentieth-century scholars. Leaving behind the biased judgments of the eighteenth-century and the emotional appeals of the nineteenth we turn now to a closer examina- tion of the modern day research as a whole, in an effort to reconstruct a more adequate picture of the early Middle Ages. 43Ih1d., p. 5. Chapter II POLITICAL TRANSITION (3rd-6th Centuries) As the hands of time moved into the midnight hour of the second century the little eddies which warned of the coming ebb were already swelling within the Roman Empire. The winds of civil strife which were brewing during this period burst forth with hurricane force upon the third century leaving the Mediterranean edifice trembling in chaos. To quell the numerous internal upheavals that plagued the Empire at this time required leadership possessing the wisdom of a Solomon and the strength of a Sampson, yet the Empire was forced to settle for the relatively lesser geniuses, Diocletian and Constantine. While it has posed a problem for scholars to be dog- matically certain as to how far the reorganization of the Empire was due to Diocletian and how far to Constantine, it has been equally difficult to fathom the degree of success eXperienced by the reforms of these geniuses. Was the colossal edifice of classical civilization re-established upon a foundation sufficient to weather such events as the barbaric invasions of the fourth and fifth centuries, or was it essentially a New Empire, ready to succumb with the slightest agitation? Did the reformers reincarnate the 23 24 robust and happy days of Augustus or was it merely a temporary lease on life prolonging the inevitable destiny of a withering age? The answers to these, and other similar problems, have been essential in molding the conflicting views concerning the formation and character of the early Middle Ages. Viewing the political reform through the sympathetic eyes of Henri Pirenne we see the Empire as a mythical marathon runner who after receiving the proverbial second wind thrusts forward with renewed vigor and strength, de- throning not only the besetting internal maladies, but possessing sufficient stamina to outdistance any external threats posed by the pressing barbarians. The appearance of this uncivilized mass ofrumanity in the provinces of the Empire created no real problem for Pirenne because he was convinced that the invaders desired not to destroy the Mediterranean unity, but only to gain a Spot in the brilliant sun of classical civilization. It was not the Germanic invasion that effected the great rupture between Antiquity and the Middle Ages, but the rapid and uneXpected advance of Islam in the seventh and eighth centuries.1 The Germanic kings who established themselves within the Latin portion of the Empire did not possess the power of a true sovereignty, but were merely generals of the Roman army honoring the true supremacy of the Emperor.2 The entire Imperial administration lHenri Pirenne, Mohammed and Charlamagne (New York, 1939), p. 2847 Medieval Cities (Garden City, 1925), p.27. 2 Ibid., p. 46. 25 was maintained. The Vandals in Africa were careful in the heat of their venture to retain the well established Roman institutions. The face of Spain and Gaul bore no marks of disfigurement as a result of the invasions and certainly 'the Goths brought no change in their reSpective areas.3 What has appeared to some students to denote a decisive alteration in the status quo, namely the Germanic invasions of the fourth and fifth centuries, long before the birth of the PrOphet, Pirenne considers to be only a super- ficial political novelty. Nothing was Changed by the Germans, who admired Roman institutions and wished to pre- serve that to which they had fallen heir. They did not introduce a new form of government. Politically, they did no worse than to replace the old uni- fied Roman State with a plurality of states.4 In this analysis Pirenne seems to have proceededon the assumption that if the Germans wrought no change, then no change took place. This proviso is fundamental for on it depends the validity of his thesis. Simply because the Germans desired no change is not sufficient evidence to claim that no changes occurred. As we shall see later, profound alterations in the status quo had already taken place before the Germans appeared on the scene. 31bid., p. 49. Ibid., p. 125. 26 Closely akin to the Pirenne thesis, in many reSpects, is the general conclusion reached by the Austrian scholar Alfons Dopsch. His thesis supports not only the belief of a continuation of the established order following the migration of the Germans, but that things continued with vast improvement. By employing all the latest archeological findings, Professor DOpsch is convinced that the Germans did not behave as enemies of Roman culture, on the con- trary, they preserved and deve10ped it. The conquest of Rome took place on different lines from the conquest of other states in political history. “The Germans did not overrun and destroy it in a savage onslaught, and then build their primitive culture on its ruins. The Roman world was won from within, by a peaceful penetration which went on for centuries. during which time they absorbed its culture and even, to a considerable extent, took over its "5 administration. DOpsch believes the Germans did not destroy Roman civilization, but had restored and magnified the fame of Rome by means of Germanic strength.6 The political organization, whiCh was now determined by the new rulers, was not a radical change which occurred instantaneously, but was the culmination of a process which had been in the makings since the first migrations. The SAlfons DOpsch, The Economic and Social Foundations of European Civilization (New York, 1931), p.386. 6Ibid. 27 old tribal existence which had so long served as the political entity of the Germans was changed considerably and had been forced into a unity which was crystalized into a tribal constitution after the final settlement. This amalgamation of various smaller tribes into greater units was brought about by the numerous wars encountered with the Romans, and as a result created a tribal kingship possess- ing a much larger following and at the same time concentrated, greater political powers within the hands of the king.7 As the prowess of these militant kings increased and they obtained still larger followings by virtue of their conquests of smaller tribes, the ultimate end was the transition to a single monarchy. Following their final settlement a monarChical form of constitution was introduced as the accepted order.8 Although that which arose was not an absolute monarchy, there was a change in the traditional democratic institutions. The authority which had formerly been vested in the peOple, in the assembly of free men, passed to the monarch and the system was decisively influ- enced by him. Actually, as Dopsch sees it, this German institution was more acceptable to the Romans than their own corrupt order, in that many Romans left their possessions and position to seek refuge among the Germans. Thus, the 7Ibid., p. 184. 81bid., p. 187. 28 abolition of Roman political sway was only a step in the long process of change, the readjustment, so to speak, “of a firm whose old name has for long ceased to describe the actual head of the business.“9 It would appear from the two theses already examined that the political status of the ancient world was un- affected by the flood of barbarians that swept over EurOpe in the fourth century. However, this emphasis on the "continuity" of the political order, which has been somewhat exaggerated by Pirenne and Dopsch, becomes more valid as we turn our attention to the work of the noted French historian, Ferdinand Lot. Professor Lot returns our attention once more to the civil chaos which had its begin- ning in the second half of the second century. With his emphasis being upon the internal maladies which plagued the Empire, he is rather dubious concerning the degree of suc- cess experienced by Diocletian and Constantine in curing those economic, social and political sores. Granted, the political genius of these two men was capable of restoring a temporary vitality and stability to the Empire, but nothing could st0p this internal degradation which con— tinued with increased propulsion in the fourth and fifth centuries. Diocletian and Constantine were able to cover the outward signs of the disease, but the malignancy which 91bid., p. 386. 29 had worked its way into the Spiritual fibers of classical life could not be removed by the most skillful political surgeon.lo One of the key problems which must be considered in this transition from Ancient to Medieval civilization, as we have encountered already in the works of DOpsch and Pirenne, is the persistence of Roman political institutions in the West after the settlement of the Germans. Essentially, Lot would agree that those institutions to which the intruders had fallen heir continued to function with some degree of efficiency throughout the fifth and sixth centuries. The Visigoths, who were masters of Spain and two-thirds of Gaul, were no more than federates to the Empire, serving often quite admirably in the Roman service.11 Although King Euric (468) repudiated the theoretical sovereignty of the Emperor, there still,existed recognition of the Roman Empire. For example, one hundred years after the death of Euric, Visigothic coins still bore the name of the Emperor.12 Furthermore, documents of the council continued to be dated in the Roman fashion with the name of the council in place. Also, the Roman financial administration continued with its defects and the legislation was entirely Roman. 1OFerdinand Lot, The End of the Ancient World and the Beginning of the Middle Age (New York, 1931) p. 60. 11Ibid., p. 243. lzIbid., p. 245. 30 This sustenance of their political inheritance can be seen among other German tribes as well as with the Goths. The Burgundians were long conscious of their dependence in relation to the imperial government and constantly turned 13 It to the Emperor for their appointment of Roman titles. is also known that the Franks were often on the best of terms with the imperial government in Constantinople. Even those Frankish kings who were opposed to the sovereignty of the Emperor were not capable of becoming completely independ- ent of the imperialtentaclea. Of all the Germanic tribes, the Vandals in Africa were probably the most hostile to imperial control, but even they were careful to maintain nany of the well established institutions of the Romans, such as their economic system.14 Thus, while it can be said that Lot essentially agrees with the “continuity" of the German's rich inherit- ance, this statement must be made with reservation. It is true they continued in many reSpects to carry on the trend of events, but the critical point is that whidh they had in- herited had already eXperienced radical alterations before they received it. Beginning with the civil chaos in the second half of the second century, it is evident that the political organi- zation of Rome was experiencing profound changes. As a 131bid., p. 246. 14Ihid., p. 248. 31 measure of SXpediency a permanent dictatorship was entrusted to the first citizen of the state, the Emperor,for the renedying of the social and political upheavals which threatened the existence of the Roman Republic.ls Although the imperial magistracy did not aim at substituting a monarchy for the republic, this was what ultimately trans— pired. It is precisely at the end of the second century that one can see an event taking place which reveals the true nature of the Roman Empire. With the assassination of the Emperor Alexander Severus and of his mother, we see in full light without concealment, the fundamental vice of Rome.16 The Roman Empire, deSpite its appearance of bril- liance, has no constitution. It rests on forCe alone, on brute force let loose by the lowest appetites. The true wielder of power in Rome was not the Emperor nor the Senate. but the army which proceeded to make and destroy possessors of the purple at will.17 It is not possible here to re- trace the history of the so-called period of the thirty tyrants: nevertheless, political upheavals continued to mount and by the end of the third-century had nearly shattered the Roman world to fragments. It was the appearance of Ibid., p. 6. 16Ibid., p. 8. l7ChristOpher Dawson, The Makigg of Europg (New York, 1932), pp. 34, 35. This work presents a conclusion concern- ing the political maladies of Rome that is very similar to Lot's. 32 Diocletian upon the front that marked the return to a relatively stable position and prevented the Empire from succumbing at thfisearly date. Thus, we can see by the time the Germans effected their encroachment of the imperial soil, the Empire was already dying. “like an old man eXpiring from decay.“ Still another thesis put forth concerning the beginning of the Middle Ages is that of H. St. L. B. Moss which stresses the death of Theodosius in 395 A.D. as the epoch making moment. At the death of Theodosius, the Empire was divided between his two sons, Arcadius, aged eighteen, inheriting the Eastern portion, and Honorius, aged eleven, the Western. This diviSion in itself did not mark a new event. The power had been divided before this time and there were certain differences long existing between the Western provinces whose culture and city-life were largely the creation of Rome, and the Eastern district which still retained the Hellenistic traidition.18 It was, however, from this time that the East and West began to drift apart until they were no longer reconcilable. Yet, it is important to note that in the eyes of the fourth century contemporaries, the Empire was still one and indivisible. This continuity was recognized by the barbarians themselves and some of their leaders genuinely 18H. St. L. B. Moss, The Birth of the Middle Ages (Oxford, 1935) p. 14. 33 supported it.19 Long after 476 A.D., the date most text- books record as the fall of Rome, the years were still dated by the names of the two consuls, one in Rome, the other in Constantinople: and imperial legislation was still enacted in the name of both Emperors. Professor Moss sees the stream of political events in the fifth and sixth centuries following two separate channels. Those areas outside of Italy were in a more rapid state of monarchical development than those within Italy. In areas such as Spain and Gaul the Roman senate had dwindled into a municipal council.20 From the third century crisis onward, the course of political events with- in the Empire was marked by the desire for stability and this was secured by a resolute fixing and simplifying of all the elements of administration.21 The Empire had to be saved at the expense of the public and this led to the develOpment of a monarchy exercising strong efforts to turn the whole organism into a standardized machine for produc- ing money and necessities. Some small degree of stability may have been adhieved, but as we shall see later in the social effects of this critical period, it left the Empire idle and lifeless. 19Ibid., p. 15. 201bid., p. 24. 211bid., p. 65. 34 Following the invasions monarchy still existed, but it was not of the Roman variety. The German kings were first and foremost military leaders and their success on the battlefield had increased their power immensely. Professor Moss agrees with Dopsch on this point, but he does not see the brilliance in it which blinds DOpsch. The German monarchy, which was being formulated along the fringe of the Empire, stood in contrast to that which had existed under Diocletian and Constantine. The assembly of free men which had continued to exist among the Germans under the late Roman Emperors, gave way under the Germanic kings to a new nobility of service gathered around the king in the form of seneschals, marshalls, constables, and other posi- tions of civil and military authority. When compared to the Roman hierarChy of officials this system was very primitive.22 The Italian kingdom of Theodoric stood apart from those of the other German rulers, for here was employed extensive efforts to preserve Roman civilization.23 Theodoric ruled over the Roman population of Italy as the Emperor's vice regent. There were no coins struck in his name and his laws were merely “edicts“ applicable only to the Italian provinces. Here the Roman civil service remained 22Ibid., p. 65. 23Ihid., p. 66. 35 intact: and at the courts there were no seneschals or marshalls, but practorion prefects. The senate continued to sit and was honored by Theodoric. Thus, we can conclude from this important analysis that the political transition did not occur at the same pace in all the Empire, but varied in different localities. The monarchy, to which reference has already been made several time, is one of the more significant issues by which we can measure the degree of political continuity eXperienced in the transition from Antiquity to the Middle Ages. The change from a "magistracy" to a “monarchy", which received its impetus under Diocletian, was first sketched by Edward Gibbon in 1778. The picture which he presented of the political transition possessed a mechanical rigidity which gave it the false appearance of being the creation of a theorist.24 The constitutional reforms of Diocletian were not the results of g priori Speculation of a political theorist, but came about simply as a force of circumstance. On the day following Diocletian's ascension to the throne (284), he realized that he would be no more success— ful in combatting the power of the army and retaining the reins of government within his own hands than his predec- essors had been, unless certain changes were invoked. It was 24Edward Gibbon, The History_of the Decline and Fall 9f the Roman Empigg, II, p. 385. 36 only too obvious that in the future the Empire could no longer be directed by a single ruler.25 Wisdom suggested that Diocletian meet the situation half way and provide himself with a colleague who was neither a rival nor an enemy. Diocletian's attention was gained by the commander- in-arms, Maximian, to whom he was already bound by a close tie of friendship. Maximian, albeit unlettered and rude, was a superior military figure and consented to being the hands for the brain which was precisely what Diocletian was seeking. Even this measure proved to be insufficient. The attacks of the Persians in Asia, and the Germans in EurOpe were too much for the two "Augusti." Thus, in 293, Diocletian went a step further in the division of power with the two Emperors taking a lieutenant who received the actual sovereignty, but with the title of “Caesar" which left them in subordination to his Augustus. The supreme power was divided, but there was no dismemberment of the Empire: legislative and administrative unity remained theoretically in the hands of the two “Augusti”, but actually it was exercised undivided by Diocletian who re- mained the mainSpring of the mechanism. Thus, what existed actually was an embryonic court with Diocletian at the head.26 25Ferdinand Lot, p. 13. 26Ibid., p. 14. 37 The task of transforming the Empire from a magistracy to a monarchy which was undertaken by Diocletian, was con- tinued by Constantine and his successors.27 The palace and the court became the center of the State and the Empire was wholly contained therein. The old organs of sovereignty were no more than a shadow. The senate, stripped of its prerogatives, was a mere ruin. Although the senate did remain as a social class, more so in the East than in the West, the government became a court government with all its pettiness. William Carroll Bark agrees that Diocletian and Constantine were powerful administrators and reformers, but "their methods in an extremely complicated situation call- ing for extraordinary insight, finesse, and encouragement of individual talent were imperceptive, clumsy and Oppres- Sive.“28 DOpsch and Pirenne may Speak of “continuity“ of the political inheritance of the Germanic tribes, as do Lot and Moss with Specific reservations, but the emphasis which the first two place upon this rich inheritance is mis- leading in that what actually remained was only fool's gold. By the end of the sixth century, the ambitious monardhical regimes were little more than facades hiding a wide variety of grave political 1113.29 There may have remained some 27Ibid., p. 86. 28William Carroll Bark, Origins of the Medieval WCrld (Stanford, 1958) p. 42. 29Richard E. Sullivan, Heirs of the Roman Empire (Ithaca, 1960) p. 39. 38 similitude of the old imperial order in the use of Roman administration and the recognition of the supremacy of the Emperor, but does this mean the Empire was saved? If so, it was only in the striking phrase of Rostovtzeff, as a “30 vast prison for scores of millions of men. It is only when we turn to the economic, social, and cultural condi- tions of the third through the sixth centuries that this phrase attains fuller meaning. 30M. Rostovtzeff, The Social and Economic History of the Roman Empire, lst ed., (Oxford, 1926) p. 478 (The second edition of this work which appeared in 1957 is in two volumns and contains many additional notes.) Chapter III ECONOMIC TRANSITION (3rd—6th Centuries) Although it has required a legion of scholars work- ing in many areas to rent the shroud of ignorance which so long enrapped the early Middle Ages, few of them deserve more credit than those who undertook the arduous task of reconstructing the edifice of late Roman and early Medieval economic institutions. While their fields of source material often appeared barren, the final harvest was plenteous, in that much was accomplished toward breaking, or at least changing, the entire concept of a "Middle Age." Just as the cultivation of any virgin field of research is often subject to a stunted yield as a result of the scholar's biases and misconceptions, the original Spade work in the economic institution of antiquity proved to be no exception. Many of the pioneenson this frontier, such as Henri Pirenne, were led astray as a result of their being blinded by the past brilliance of classical civilization. They could not conceive of a civilization possessing the grandeur which the Romans had once possessed, falling into a state of internal decay and succumbing so early in life. As a result of their blindness, they created a picture of late Roman and early Medieval economic institutions as 39 40 possessing a vitality and stability Which actually did not exist. Although the errors of these early pathfinders are in our own age evident, as we shall see, it would be more than a minor misdemeanor to dismiss this original work as being futile, in that it was the labors of these men which served as the vital catalyst which solidified future interpretations. Viewing, once more, the posthumously published work of Henri Pirenne, Mohammed and Charlamagne, we see the author exercising the same exuberant verbosity in stressing the economic continuity of classical civilization through- out this so-called “dark age", as he exercised in stressing the political continuity. He persistently maintains that while the appearance of the Germans may have initiated a brief reign of chaos, the calm returned after the tempest leaving the Mediterranean unity as it had existed prior to the invasions.l The author erroneously sees numerous utterances in the work of Gregory of Tours as indications that the economic unity of the Mediterranean continued to exist until the seventh and eighth centuries when the “mare nostra“ finally became a Moslem lake. Through the colored glasses of Pirenne this thesis of an economic continuity can easily be validated by a close scrutiny of the primary sources concerning the commercial __ lHenri Pirenne, Mohammed and Charlamagne, (New York, 1939), p. 75. 41 activity of the day. He became extremely dogmatic in refer- ence to the flourishing commercial movement which he saw existing between the Eastern and Western portions of the Mediterranean. Although the emminent British scholar, Norman H. Baynes, has since suggested that the economic unity of the Mediterranean was shattered in the fifth century by the Vandal pirate fleet in Africa, Pirenne dis- missed these piracies of the barbarians as only a hindrance to the trade whidh continued to move as actively as ever.2 In support of this extensive commercial activity which Pirenne sees existing, great emphasis is placed upon the large number of Oriental merchants that were present within the West during the fifth and sixth centuries. With the chief commercial agents of the day being the Syrians from the East, the author sees the redundant references to their presence as being proof of a commercial activity. Had there not been a considerable profit rendered during this period the appearance of the Syrians within the records of the West would have vanished much sooner than they did. Yet, Southern Gaul leaves evidence of large number of these Oriental merchants whose business it was to tranSport mer- chandise from the East to the West: and in addition to 2Norman H. Baynes, "The Decline of Roman Power in Western Europe,“ The Journal 9f Roman StudiesL XXXIII (1943), p.29-35. Archibald Lewis, Naval Power and Trade in the Mediterranean A. D. 500-1000, (Princeton, 1951), p.19: believes Baynes exaggerates the power of the Vandal fleet. 42 those who traveled to and fro there was also a large number who established permanent residence within Gaul.3 Further proof of a commercial continuity during the post-invasion period is the large number of luxuries that were to be found in the West. Frequent reference is made by Gregory of Tours to the numerous ivory carvings, decorative liturgical tunics, oriental curtains, and silks which existed in the West and could have had as their origins no other place than the Eastern Mediterranean. Also, there was a prodigious amount of table luxuries which must have proceeded from the East. The wines of Syria could be found in large quantities and the bitter herbs of Egypt were imported for ascetic consumption during the Lenten season. But most important was the extensive Spice trade that existed.4 M. Pirenne thinks it would be impossible to exaggerate the significance of Oriental Spices in the West, in that they continued after the Germanic invasions, as before them, to form an important constituent of the everyday diet. Spices were to be found on practically every table in the West. While the material already mentioned was essential in Pirenne's effort to support his economic thesis, one of the most vital points was the amount of gold that existed in the West after the invasion. If there was such an 3Pirenne, Mohammed and Charlamagne, p. 82. 4Ibid., p. 89. 43 extensive commercial activity it would demand an equally extensive amount of gold to have been present. Here Pirenne did not falter as he saw the Germanic kings, quite successfully, employing the imperial economic system. The abundance of gold whidh Pirenne saw flowing in the West at this time could not be described by even his lucrative storehouse of adjectives. The Roman gold “solidus,” which had been adjusted by Constantine, continued to serve as the monetary unit throughout the Empire. This monetary system, with which the Germans had long been acquainted while serving the Empire, was preserved after their final triumph as the accepted financial standard. Nothing attributes more clearly the persistence of the economic unity of the West during the fifth and sixth centuries than this retention of the Roman monetary system.5 The economic standards of the barbarians were those of Rome and no alterations were made until the introduction of the silver monometallism during the Carolinian period. For Pirenne, there is no doubt that the economic unity of Rome continued with all its Splendor into the post-invasion period. Alfons Dopsch is another who maintains it is impos- sible to represent the post-invasion period as one when free commerce was restricted. The Germans, after peacefully 51bid., p. 107. 44 penetrating the Empire, did not upset the existing order of trade, but actually served as a stimulant to it. The Gothic kings looked very favorably upon commercial activity and in the course of events even passed significant legis- lation which resulted in increased activity.6 The Germans had long been in contact with Roman economic organizations and had deve10ped considerable knowledge of its functions whidh permitted a continuation of these activities after their final settlement. In regards to the large number of Oriental merchants living in the Western Mediterranean and their transporting from the East suCh products as silks, Spices, paper and rare wines, it is wrong to suppose that ttade in this early period of the Middle Ages was carried on exclusively, or even mainly, by foreigners, and that the trade was limited to luxuries.7 The monasteries were not at this early date self-sufficient and yet they were capable of supplying their needs by purChasing such items as cloth and grain in the local market place and these are certainly not luxury items. Also, much of this trade was being carried on by the local population in addition to the efforts of the Syrians. Even the clergy can be seen engaging in extensive trade, under assumed names, in an effort to reap some of the lucrative rewards. The German participation in commercial activities gAlfons Dopsch, The Economic and Social Foundations f European Ciyilization (New York, 1937), pp.340—41. 7Ibid., p. 344. 45 should not be difficult to accept, says Professor Dopsch, because archaeological findings have proved that trade had been going on between Rome and the Germans since the third century, whidh gave them a considerable background in economic dealings.8 This long established trade did not cease with the fall of Rome, but just assumed a new partner. Thus, the migration of the Germans into the Empire had not created economic chaos, but actually made new connections which in return created increased commercial activity.9 Migrations have always brought mankind closer to- gether and has often brought different civilizations into touch so that gulfs were bridged and cultures could be transmitted one to the other. The migration of the Germans proved to be just such an event in that it eventually stimulated the economic life of the Mediterranean which continued to flourish until the ninth century. Returning once more to the evidence produced by Dopsch's grave-diggings and other archaeological endeavors, he concludes that evidence has been sufficient to support the belief of a continuous employment of the Roman coinage by the Germans after the invasions. The coins whidh have been discovered illustrate that the Germans were familiar 10 with the Roman currency and wanted to preserve it. The lack 8 Ibid., pp. 347-48. 91bid., p. 348. lOIbid., p. 359. 46 (of German coins during the early invasion period does not rnean they were incapable of producing their own, but iactually indicates there was such a great abundance of .Roman coins that the Germans had no need of minting new. lNhen they did commence striking their own coins, which em- ibodied the effigy of the Emperor, they were so genuinely produced that it is difficult to distinguish them from the Roman.11 According to D0psch, this is sufficient evidence to support the belief that the Germans actually possessed sufficient knowledge and craftsmanship to continue the imperial economic order. While Pirenne and DOpsch are in general agreement concerning the continuity of the established economic order during the fifth and Sixth centuries, this does not mean they are necessarily correct in their conclusion. Pirenne exhibits a unique ability to take the arrival of a few ships in the West, of which we are not even certain they came directly from the East, and construct a flourishing trade: while at the same time Professor Dopsch can make a mint out of the appearance of a few coins. William C. Bark may not have been too far wrong when he concluded that these men had not only the ability to make bricks without straw, but at times they didn't even need clay.12 In order that a more Ibid., p. 359. 12William C. Bark, Origins of the Medieval World. (Stanford, 1958), p. 13. 47 accurate account may be formulated of the late Roman and early medieval economic conditions, it will be necessary to turn now to the crisis of the third century and view its effect upon the economic institutions. In the words of Ferdinand Lot, "It is an established fact that the Roman world underwent a serious economic up- heaval . . . from the second half of the second century on- wards. “1 3 With the advancement of the third century, this decline, which expressed itself most vividly in a debasement of the coinage, became more and more marked. The once stable imperial weight of the coins has now become extremely irregular and their make abominable. The portion of the base metal had risen to an astonishing 98.5 percent, with the silver coins becoming no more than a piece of copper or lead dipped in silver wash.l4 While Diocletian and Constantine were able to restore a sound coinage of the silver products, the gold “solidus,” which was the basis of their economy, was already becoming rare. In Spite of the measures to curb the economic maladies, unmistakable signs made it clear that ancient society was in a state of economic retrogression with the monetary economy yielding more and more to a natural economy. 13Ferdinand Lot, The End of the Ancient Werld and the Eeginning_of the Middle AqesL (New York, 1931), p. 55. H. St. L.B. Moss, The Birth of the Middle Ages 395—814,(Oxford, 1935), p. 8 and Robert Latouche, The Birth of the Western Economy (New York, 1961).p. 3, also agrees that the Empire eXperienced profound economic upheavals during this period. léLot, p. 56; William Carroll Bark, p. 51. 48 Thus far there has been no mention of a natural economy because with all the gold whidh Pirenne and DOpsch saw existing within the West, they would have dismissed as ignorance any attempt to see the slightest degree of a natural economy prevailing within the Empire. iowever, the verdict of recent scholarship would not coincide with the conclusions of these two historians. By the end of the third and the beginning of the fourth centuries, the Roman state had started the practice of receiving the land tax most often in kind and to these receipts in kind corresponded salaries in kind.15 This is not meant to assert that a complete change from pay in money to pay in kind took place in the third century. There was by no means a thorough replacement of gold economy by a natural economy. It is best qualified as being a partial natural economy. As Professor M. Rostovtzeff has pointed out, there were wide variations of conditions within the Empire, and what went on in one part at any given time did not, of necessity, go on in all.16 Evidence of this can be seen in the Eastern portion of the Empire as this segment of the ancient world was able to restore a relatively stable economy while the West passed into greater poverty. 15Lot, The End of the Ancient world, p. 57: Bark, Origins of the Medieval WOrldL p. 53: Moss, The Birth of the Middle Ages, p. 9. 16Rostovtzeff, “The Decay of the Ancient world and Its Economic Explanation.“ Economic Historical Review, II, (1929-1930). pp. 200—201. 49 As a result of these profound economic upheavals whiCh infested the ancient world, society became very dis- illusioned, indebted, and insecure with their present stations in life. As the very capable French scholar , Robert Latouche, has pointed out in his work, The Birth of Western Economyy the problems of the second and third centuries became so devastating in the fourth and fifth centuries that they were highlighted by an extensive exodus to the large estates.17 Many individuals sought security by placing themselves into the hands of men more powerful in order that they might gain their guardianship and pro- tection.18 The residents of the city left their declining and insecure positions to seek refuge on the large estates. The small, free farmers, that were numerous at this time, became so indebted and unable to meet the demands of the fisc that they also relinquished their status as freemen to gain protection from their more powerful neighbor, the large landlord. With the eclipse of city life the rural economy assumed a position of greatest importance in the survival of the medieval world. As we shall see in the next chapter, so significant was the agrarian class that the government was impelled to take action which would ensure the continued services of this economic entity. More important, however, 17Robert Latouche, p. 21. lBIbid., p. 23. 50 than the economic aSpects of the large estates, was that they represented one of the few institutions that was capable of existing amidst an otherwise Chaotic world. This system which brought together former slaves now freemen, small landowners weighed down with debts, barbarians, and the discontented elements of city life, was so successful that it was later to be adOpted by the Germanic aristocracy and in the process became one of the moulding attributes of the new Western world.19 Additional repercussions set in motion by these economic upheavals can be seen in the deterioration of the military order. With the absence of specie entailing the disappearance of pay, the costly Roman anmy was soon replaced by barbarian trOOps using their won weapons, fighting under their own chiefs, and receiving land as payment for their services. Professor Lot is correct in his conclusion that, "the inevitable consequences of a system which allows services rendered to be rewarded by means of salaries in kind or the distribution of land...is the emergence of the so—called feudal system."20 We are now faced with a problem of highest importance. How can we eXplain the fact that the Roman world,;economically prOSperous.at the end of the Republiczperiod and during the lgIbid., p. 19. 20Latouche, p. 123. 51 first two centuries of the Empire, was now irreparably ruined? As Professor Lot eXplainS it, the population had been steadily decreasing in number and their buying power was very poor.21 The man of antiquity had few needs. Their food was simple as was the clothing which they required. Thus, with the frugality and simplicity in whidh man lived there was little Opportunity for the develOpment of industry.22 Even the rich lived off the products of their own estates and their greatest need was in luxuries, which involved only a fragment of society and was absolutely inadequate to create or maintain a thriving industry. While it is true that commerce held on infinitely more important positions in antiquity and the Middle Ages than did industry, even this never reached any tremendous volume in the West. Producing little the Roman world had little to sell, and as William C. Bark has stated, this un- favorable balance of trade created a constant drain on the 23 Western economy. After the transference of the capital from West to East in 330 A.D., the center of world trade had moved with it and from this time on Constantinople grows at the expense of Rome.24 21Arthur, E. R. Boak, Manppwer Shortage and the Fall of the Empire, (Ann Arbor, 1955). Moses I. Finley, “Manpower Shortage,“ The Journal of Roman Studies, XLVIII (1958), p. 156-164, taEES Opposition to the significance which Boak places on the manpower shortage and states this is not the key to the decline of the Empire. 22Lot, p. 73. 23Bark, p. 47. 24Moss. D. 16. 52 In spite of the valid warnings of Professors Norman H. Baynes and M. Rostovtzeff, too little emphasis is still placed upon the role Of the East concerning the economic life of the late Empire. It is only by looking at the East that the decline of the West can best be understood. What ‘was saved out of the wreckage of the third century and the reforms Of the fourth? Certainly not the Empire Of Augustus. What was salvaged was a new Opportunity for the Eastern Empire, and it is a mistake to consider that the complete Empire of classical times continued intact. The old Roman Empire gave up the ghost in the rigors, eXpedients, and compulsions that brought new life for the East. The East had experienced economic recovery but the West was quite otherwise. The East curbed those tendencies that ran free in the West. AS we have already seen in the writings of Pirenne and DOpsch, the Western economy, if not closely examined, will tend to give a false impression Of robustness which it actually did not possess. Certainly there was gold remain- ing in the West through the sixth century, but how extensive was it and how long did it remain there? It is certain that a good deal of it had already found its way back to the 25 It is well known that East from whence it came. Constantinople escaped capture from the barbarians time after time by bribing the would-be attackers with gold, 25Bark, p. 48. 53 vflnereas the West had to go through such difficulties without tfllis advantage.26 The East did not hesitate to sacrifice tile West, nor Rome itself, as can be seen with the Visigoths annd again with the Huns, in an effort to protect herself. (The meaning is clear: the East could afford to buy protec- ‘tion with money: the poorer West could not and therefore laad to suffer the fate the East escaped. The West, no longer self-sustaining and an active partner, was in the process Of being gleaned: its provinces 'were being plundered, its cities destroyed or abandoned. The trade of the West had fallen into the hands of the Oriental merchants, primarily the Syrians andJews.27 It is true, as Pirenne stated, that these Eastern merchants did prosper or they would not have remained in the West, but this was made possible, primarily, by the supply of gold that was arriving periodically in the West as tribute money to the Merovingian kings from the Eastern Emperors. This gave the West an appearance Of prOSperity which it actually did not possess. From the Eastern point Of view these merchants were bold, capable businessmen, able to make money even under the unproductive, adverse conditions in the West. From the Western point Of View they were foreigners, (1 hated because of their wealth and Byzantine connections.20 26Ibid., p. 48. 27Lot, p. 81. 28Bark, p. 50. 54 Professor Latouche is correct when he concludes that the presence of these Syrian merdhants in the West was not to suggest prOSperity, but decline. It was the deteriora- tion Of commercial activity resulting from the great in— vasions that Spread over Gaul and Italy which brought these eastern traders with hope of making a substantial profit from the bundle of wares they had brought with them. More- over, the goods in which they dealt were not always reSpect- able with slaves being the most profitable Of their wares.29 Contrary to what DOpsch may believe, the Germans were too primitive in their economic manners to bring order out of the chaos and this presented tremendous Opportunity for the foreign merchants.3O Also, as Professor Norman Baynes has pointed out, even the presence of these merchants in the West does not necessarily indicate that a coastal trade existed. The term "merchant“ has been eXpanded by modern day economic historians to include more than was originally intended. Many Of these persons who bore the title "merchant“ were in- volved primarily with local trade. This is by no means to indicate that they were in communication with the East nor that their numbers were being replenished by new arrivals.‘51 29Latouche, p. 123. 30Ibid. ,p. 123 31Norman Baynes, ”The Decline of the Roman Power in Western EurOpe. Some Modern Explanations," The Journal of Roman Studies, XXXIII (1943), pp. 310-316. 55 'There is actually little to suggest that there was any tremendous commercial activity existing during the post- invasion period. By the end of the sixth century, it is inconceivable to think that the barbarians continued an extensive economic program, for there was little to continue. It znust be added, however, that there were efforts to use those economic institutions which did remain. There is evidence to support the fact that they continued to collect the in- direct tax, such as tolls, but at the same time, were in- capable Of collecting the direct tax which would have been their greatest source of revenue. It is now evident that by no stretch Of the imagination can it be maintained that a brilliant economy existed. Trade was stagnant, the coinage was debased, gold was rapidly being drained from the West, mines were depleted, and a partial natural economy was pre- vailing. Any accurate statement concerning the continuity of an economy order following the invasions must, Of necessity, include these grave reservations. In conclusion, we can see that the actual beginning of the Middle Ages economically was not a catastrophic break, but rather a gradual transition which permitted the Germans to retain a small degree of the classical economic order. Had the Germans been further removed from the stages of barbarism than they were, they may be could have salvaged more. But as we shall see, the events following the sixth century became even more deplorable than before. Chapter IV SOCIAL TRANSITION (3rd-6th Centuries) In Spite of the rigorous reform efforts of Diocletian and Constantine, the tide of social life within the Empire had descended to a level of rigidity and lifelessness. That there was no political life goes without saying, but there was scarcely any municipal life either. Theprodigious expense of maintaining the Empire continued to mount while the ability Of the populous to meet such an expense con- tinually dwindled. The demands of the fisc had become most unbearable. The position of the Empire could be likened to that Of a ruined landlord who tries to live with the same degree of public diSplay after the cessation Of his prosperity as he did before. With the growing strength of the barbarians and the inability of the State to OOpe with them, society lived with the constant threat of invasion. Not only had the Empire lost all power Of conquest, but was rapidly losing even its capacity for assimilating the barbarians. With these conditions surrounding them the oppressed public became so ill at ease at their present position in life that exhaustive efforts were being made to flee it. Peasants were leaving the country, workmen abandoned their trade, and the decurion fled the municipal 57 senate.1 Haunted by the memory of the anarchy which had so nearly shattered the Empire in the third century by renewed threats of disorder, by the stirring of the barbarian hordes just beyond its ill-defended frontier, the government in the fourth century could see but one means of securing the Empire, which was vacilating amidst instability, and that was to be invoked at the expense of the public. It was during this low tide of social life that the government had recourse to the deSperate measures of forcing men to remain in their economic status, regardless of the hardships which it inflicted, in an effort to preserve production, public service, and tax income.2 Efficacious steps were taken to eliminate every possible outlet through which escape could be made. The daily watchword became, “Everyone at his post, or Roman civilization would perish.“ Thus, with this immobilizing philOSOphy dominant, the whole organism of society was soon transformed into a blighting standardized machine, destroying in the process the last remains of the already waning public Spirit. The method that we are describing by which various elements Of society became bound to their stations was the institution enforced by Diocletian known as the Caste System. Although this institution was by no means novel at this time, 1FerdinandiLot, The End of the Ancient WOrld and the Beginning of the Middle Ages, (New York) 1931, p. 100. 2William Carroll Bark, Origins of the Medieval World, (Stanford, 1958), p. 47, 48. 58 as the ancient monarchies of Asia and Egypt had long used it to tie the peasants to the soil, it was now being expanded to include practically every phase of life.3 In their efforts to save the Empire, the emperors sought to embrace everyone that was essential to the continu- ation of the classicaltradition. The first group to be affected by this regimentation was naturally those public servants whose fidelity to the state was most urgently needed.4 with much Of the trouble existing within the Empire during the third and fourth centuries Springing from the economic upheavals and the continual diminishment of Specie, the b‘tate owned and Operated mines became one of the earliest institutions to be regimented. with hOpe to curb these economic maladies, employment in the imperial mines conse- quently became regimented and eventually even hereditary. For who would have accepted voluntarily a life so horrible as that of an ancient miner? Following a similar course the vast number of artisans who were needed to maintain the splendor of Rome, with their production of essential domestic utensils and other more decorative handicraft, were also affected by these saving efforts of the emperors, as their stations in life became 3’erdinand Lot, p. 108. 41bid., p. 101. 59 bound by a life sentence which was to pass from father to son. The son of a craftsman was required to marry the daughter of a fellow craftsman in an imperial attempt to perpetuate this institution, and if any artisan even con- templated escape from his position in society he was readily subjected to adverse treatment.5 As the regimentation Of society continually gained in momentum, a comparable fate was soon to befall all civil servants. The armourers and smiths of the imperial factory were bound to their stations. Cartwrights, veterinary surgeons, weavers, and all posts of significance became frozen in organized “colleges," subject to a military type regulation and discipline. Those charged with the tranSport— ation of taxes, which were now'being paid largely in kind, and with the preparation of these receipts for public usage, were also bound socially. The maintenance of buildings and even the gladiatorial games became tightly regulated insti— tutions.6 Theatrical personnel and charioteers were for- bidden to leave the cities and even became subject to the obligation of fixed residence. It was only through such means as this that the State was assured of the continual service of its personnel. Unfortunately, this system did not remain as a chain to bind civil servants alone, but was eventually eXpanded Ibid. Ibid., p. 103. 60 to include other phases of life as well. For example, the imperial military organization was touched by this caste system. Roman citizens had long ceased to do military duty and the reSponsibility Of recruiting new man power had be- come the task of the large landlords. Every lord was re- quired to provide at least one or more recruits from amongst the so-called free men living on his estate.7 Once these men were enlisted they were required to take an oath of allegiance which bound then to service, leaving their posi- tion unaltered, until their strength was exhausted which usually involved over twenty years of military duty. The soldiers were permitted to enter a contract of marriage,but the children of such a union was to be the prOperty Of the army. It is neither surprising nor difficult to understand that the value of an army whose function had fallen to the bonds Of strict servitude soon became a disgrace and their achievements eanperatingly poor. Antiquity would have no doubt tumbled much earlier had it not adopted the practice of filling its ranks with barbarians.8 As we have already seen, by the close of the third century, it was no longer plausible for the Empire to attempt to survive from the rapidly diminishing fruits Of commerce and industry. Thus, the basis of survival passed into the 7Ibid., p. 105. Ibid., p. 106. 61 hands of peasants.9 With this class now occupying such a strategic position within the life Of the Empire it became necessary to coerce them in an effort to stabilize their production. Having become the new life line of classical civilization, the station of the coloni, or free farmer, was rapidly regimentized, placing them within the same strata of social organization as their contemporaries.lo During the early history Of Rome, which witnessed the transformation from a Republic to an Empire, agricultural production never posed a real problem, as the labor force of the Empire was being steadily replenished by the slaves tw