m—nuuww-n.~v.,.,_.‘,,,,-‘~-,'.r.'\ THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT: A STUDY IN THE HISTORY OF ACCOUNTINGTHOUGHT THESIS FOR THE DEGREE 0F Ph. D. ' MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY , ' CLIEFORD BROWN 1968 H 6.19" LIBRARY “ Michic in State University This is to certify that the thesis entitled THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT: A STUDY IN THE HISTORY OF ACCOUNTING THOUGHT presented by Clifford D. Brown has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for PhoD degree in Accounting ,flflfl/m Major professor Date November 14 , 1968 0—169 Clifford Brown This dissertation is a study in the history of accounting thought and it seeks to identify the nature of the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting report. It also presents the more important forces reSponsible for this ascendancy of the income statement utilizing an historical approach based upon the interpretation of ideas and events. In this study old corporate annual reports, selected accounting literature, correspondence and internal income state- ments from selected companies, governmental publications and legislative acts, and interviews, where appropriate, were the basic raw materials. The organizational scheme was to deter— mine the interrelationships between past ideas and events in- fluencing accounting actions. Under this approach both exogenous and endogenous environmental variables can be related to the study. The conclusion reached in Chapters III and IV was that there were essentially two shifts in emphasis from balance sheet data to income statement data. There was an internal or managerial shift and an external shift by stockholders, creditors, and other parties outside the firm. The former shift, it was contended, probably occurred with the advent of the corporate form of business organization between 1880 and 1925. On the other hand, the latter shift began in the 19203, accelerated in the 19305, and was essentially completed by the early 19HOS. The internal shift in emphasis was more difficult to docu— ment than was the external shift. Information in the form of letters, internal income statements, interviews, or combinations Clifford Brown of all three was obtained from various selected companies. This information related to the nature and extent of internal income reporting prior to the external shift in emphasis. From this information it was concluded that there was no significant internal shift in emphasis in the early 19308. The external shift in emphasis was influenced by many forces. The rise of the corporation was very important. It prompted Professor Paton and others to focus attention on the entity concept and the going-concern assumption. The emergence of the investor's vieWpoint due to the rapid growth of stock ownership by the general public created a new demand for infor- mation. Investors sought growth as well as the safety of their original investment. The income statement was useful for this purpose because it yielded profit data very essential in analy- zing investment alternatives. The rapid fluctuation in the prices of goods and services that began in the early 19203 left doubt as to the adequacy of the balance sheet as a statement of values. But Federal taxa- tion of income and related court decisions were the most im- portant developments contributing to the emergence of income reporting via the matching concept. Federal tax laws have con- sistently required the cost basis for such items as depreciation and inventories. This requirement naturally contributed to the demise of the balance sheet as a statement of values and its replacement with a statement of unallocated or residual costs. The courts also influenced the emergence of the matching concept because they became involved with the problem of identifying what was income. In the famous decision of Eisner V. Macomber Clifford Brown it was held that income did not exist until it was severed from capital. This meant that for most types of property income could emerge only through sale or exchange of the property. Thus accountants concentrated on rules and procedures that would identify a severance or sale of assets. As a result the transactions approach to income determination based upon the realization concept became the general rule. THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT: A STUDY IN THE HISTORY OF ACCOUNTING THOUGHT .3600 by CliffordrBrown A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Financial Administration 1968 -9 Copyright by CLIFFORD DEAN BROWN I968 Acknowledgments A dissertation writer is always indebted to many others: first of all, to those whose researches and scholarly activities provided the sources upon which he draws. Furthermore, I wish to add a special word of acknowledgment to my committee, par— ticularly the chairman, Dr. Roland F. Salmonson. I owe my wife, Carolyn E. Brown, a special debt for her diligent typing and re-typing of the many rough drafts. Lastly, many thanks must be added for the typing of the final copy to Margaret Scanlin. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . TABLE OF CONTENTS . . . . . . . LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS . . . . . . . . . Chapter I. AN HISTORICAL APPROACH TO ACCOUNTING . . . . Introduction Philosophy of History Some Problems in the Study of History Approaches to the Study of History of Accounting Thought II. GENERAL HISTORY OF FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING General Financial Accounting: Pre-adamite Financial Accounting — 1900 to 1929 Financial Accounting - 1930 to 19H2 Financial Accounting - Contemporary III. THE INTERNAL SHIFT FROM THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT . . . . . . . . . . . . . General The New Emphasis on Profits Evidence of the Internal Shift Summary IV. THE EXTERNAL SHIFT FROM THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT . . . . . . . . . . . General Documentation of the External Shift From the Balance Sheet to the Income Statement Factors Affecting the External Shift Summary V. THE INTERACTION OF ECONOMIC THEORIES OF PROFIT AND ACCOUNTING THEORY . . . . . . . . . . . . Introduction Importance of Profit Theory in Economics Concept of Profit as a Class Income The Concept of Profit as Surplus Remuneration to the Entrepreneur Summary of the Concept of Profit as Surplus Remuneration to the Entrepreneur Relationship of the Economist's Concept of Profit as Surplus Entrepreneurial Remuneration to Accounting The Concept of Profit as a Return to Uncertainty Bearing iii Page ii .iiiiv 16 37 7:4 105 V. — Interaction with Current Accounting Thought and Practice VI. THE INFLUENCE OF FEDERAL TAXATION 8 LEGISLATION . . . . 1H6 General Federal Income Taxation The Influence of the Securities and Exchange Commission Summary VII. SUMMARY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173 iv Number I. II. III. IV. VI. VII. VIII. IX. XI. XII. XIII. LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS Page General Electric Consolidated Balance Sheet, January 31, 1895.... 23 List of Selected Companies Contacted .............. 5” Sample Copy of Letter Mailed to H5 Selected Companies...... ......................... . ....... 55 Westinghouse Electric Statement of Consolidated Income and Profit 8 Loss for the Year Ended March 31, 1928 ........ 61 Westinghouse Electric Comparative Statement of Operations for the Period Ended March 31, 1928... ......... . ...... 62 Allied Chemical 8 Dye Corporation Methods Bulletin in Use Before 1930 ..... ........ 6” List of Manufacturing Cost Controlling Accounts. 65 Selling Expense Classification Showing the Grouping of Selling Expense Accounts.......... 66 General Administration Expense Classification Showing the Grouping of General Administration Expense Accounts............................ 67 American Telephone and Telegraph Company Combined Earnings and Expenses All Bell Operating Companies in U.S. Including American Telephone and Telegraph Company........................70 American Telephone and Telegraph Company Comparative Statement of Earnings and Expenses...7l List of Annual Reports Reviewed ..... .... ........... 81 General Electric Consolidated Profit and Loss Account of January 31, 1895..... ......................... . ........ 83 General Electric Comparative Statement of Income and Expenses.....8u United States Rubber Company and Subsidiary Companies Consolidated Income Statement for Year Ending MarCh 31’ 1903.00.......0...0.0.00.00000000000086 United States Rubber Company and Subsidiary Companies Consolidated Income... ..................... . ..... 87 CHAPTER I AN HISTORICAL APPROACH TO ACCOUNTING Introduction This dissertation will be a study of one phenomenon in the history of accounting thought. Specifically, it will be concerned with the ascendancy of the income statement to the status once held by the balance sheet as the primary accounting report. What were the underlying forces, both direct and indirect, that influenced this shift in emphasis? But before this task is attempted the methodological approach, as in any research, should be explained. Thus, the purpose of this chapter is to introduce a philosophy of history and relate this philosophy to the history of accounting thought. Philosophy of History Origin and Meaning of the Term The term "philosophy of history" was coined by Voltaire in the eighteenth century to simply mean critical or scienti- fic thinking where the historian made up his mind for himself instead of repeating the stories found in old works. However, the term today is used in several different senses: 2. 1. To denote the principiant considera— tion of the meaning, the methods, and the canons of historical science. 2. To denote inquiry into certain highly complex phases and products of historical development - as the history of institutions or of civilization. 3. To denote the explanation, from philosophical principles, of historical phenomena at large or the entire course of historical development. The first sense is of importance to this study because a philosophy of history of this kind would be directed at the problems resulting from an organized inquiry into one phenomenon of the history of accounting thought-—the change in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement. To illustrate the importance of this first sense of the term philosophy of history, it seems appropriate to trace its own historical development. However, to do this it is necessary first to define philOSOphy. Among the various definitions of philosophy there are some that are important in tracing the development of the philosophy of history to be used in this study: a study of the processes governing thought and conduct; originally, love of wisdom or knowledge; the general principles or laws of a field or knowledge, activity, etc. These definitions of philosophy are directly useful as a starting point in tracing the origins of the philosophy of history. Yet they are much lJames Mark Baldwin, Dictionary of Philosophy and Psy- chology (New York: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 1955), p. H77 3 too brief to provide a real understanding of the scope and nature of philosophy. Therefore, for the essence of philos- ophy the writer refers to the following quotation from Collingwood: Philosophy is reflective. The philoso— phizing mind never simply thinks about an object; it always, while thinking about any object, thinks also about its own thought about that object. Philosophy may thus be called thought of the second degree, thought about thought. For example, to discover the distance of the earth from the sun is a task for thought of the first degree; to discover what it is exactly what we are doing when we discover the distance of the earth from the sun is a task for thought of the second degree--in this instance for logic or the theory of science...thus thought in it re— lation to its object is not mere thought but knowledge...for philosophy the theory of knowledge.2 Thus, it might be said that philosophy is an attitude toward knowledge, not just knowledge itself. Over the cen— turies this attitude toward knowledge or, as it is called, our philosophical tradition, has gradually changed. In sixth- century Greece the foundations of mathematics were in the fore- front. When Greek philosophers discussed their attidude toward knowledge, they concentrated foremost on the theory of mathematical knowledge. In the Middle Ages, theology was at the center of the picture, and the problems of philosophy were concerned with the relations of God and man. From the end of the Middle Ages to roughly the nineteenth century, the attitude toward knowledge was concentrated on natural science, with the 2R. G. Collingwood, The Idea of History (London, England: Oxford University Press, 19MB}, pp. 1—2. u relation of the human mind to the natural world. In this latter period peOple started thinking seriously about history. The result was the conclusion that a theory of knowledge based on mathematics, theology, or science could not answer all the problems involved in historical inquiry. Historical thought had its own object and its own idiosyncrasies. For example, it was realized that the past could not be per- ceived by mathematical thinking because mathematical thinking involved objects with no special location in time and space, whereas, historical thought was concerned with particular events in time and space. In addition, it was discovered that theological thinking, concerned with an infinite object, was also inappropriate because historical thought involved events that were finite and plural. Lastly, scientific thinking based upon observation and experiment was also considered by most to be inappropriate to historical thinking because the past has vanished and ideas about it cannot be Verified like scientific hypotheses.3 As a result of this awareness that historical know- ledge cannot proceed on the assumptions of mathematical, theological, or scientific knowledge, a new phiIOSOphy began to Gamerge in the nineteenth century. This new philosophy was a twesult of the philoSOphical problems created by an organ— iz“Sicisystem of historical research and is now known as the Philosophy of history. 3Paul Edwards, Editor-in-Chief, The Encyclopedia of Philosophy (New York: The Macmillan Company, Inc.,1967), pp. 2H7-25H. 5 The next sections will be concerned with the mechanics of the new philoSOphy of history. It is important that its nature, object, method and value be explained not only because of the implications to the history of accounting thought, but because the three traditional philosophies of mathematics, theology and science imply that historical knowledge is im— possible. The ObjectiVe of Historical Inquiry The object of historical research obviously is implied in the above reference to the phiIOSOphy of history. Yet it seems appropriate that this object of history be explicitly stated in order that the object of the history of accounting thought, and consequently this study, can be clarified. The object of the "literary historian" is to write about the grandeur of the past for its own sake. Many great works have been written with this object in mind. David Hume's History of England and Edward Gibbon's The Decline and £311 of the Roman Empire are two such examples. In aCczounting, examples of "literary history" are: Arthur H. w0C>lf's A Short History of Accountants and Accounting and R0hmart H. Montgomery's Fifty_Years of Accountancy. The object of the "scientific historian" is research or iIlquiry aimed at discovering actions of human beings that have occurred in the past. Actions of the past are not dis— covered simply for their own sake. They are discovered be- cause they help provide a perspective for making wise 6 . H . ch01ces today. In accounting there are at least two books written with this object in mind: A. C. Littleton and V. K. Zimmerman's Accounting Theory: Continuity and Change and Harvey T. Deinzer's Development of Accountinnghought. A quotation from the former illustrates this "scientific" approach: As a basis for an examination of the ideas'behind accounting actions, it is convenient to consider first the nature and usefulness of accounting theory viewed in a historical perspective. Behind all transmitted methods, there must have been motivating ideas. If deter- mined, these motivating ideas of accountancy should help to explain why accounting has been able to serve so well for so mag/centuries and why it still shows such a remarkable capacity of growth in service potential. Similarly, a quotation from the latter also illustrates the scientific approach: The historical premise is that events are interactions; the latter have both antecedents and consequences. The more influential of the events are brought for- ward against a backdrop of the condition- ing of environment. Further perspective may be develOped by advancing certain of the characteristic events, say the "accounting events," towards the lens position, while leaving the other factors in the background as a conditioning flux.6 uCollingwood, op, cit., pp. 7—9 5A. C. Littleton and V.K. Zimmerman, Accounting Theory: gzfllinuity and Change (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice- Hall, Inc., 19627, p. 3 6Harvey T. Deinzer, Development of Accounting Thought (New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, Inc., 19657, p. 10 Historical Methodology Historical methodology must also be satisfactorily explained for a complete understanding of the philosophy of history. There is unanimous agreement among historians that historical methodology consists of the interpretation of evidence. But there is disagreement as to what consti- tutes historical evidence and how it is utilized in history. Traditionally, historical evidence was that which depended upon the testimony of others. Here the historian decided upon that which he wanted to know and then went to seuxrch for statements made by persons at the time of the etmants, or by eyewitnesses, or by repeating what eyewitnesses saixj, and so on for his evidence. This type of evidence is vefiluable to the "scientific historian" if it helps him to Inakus a decision. It is useless to him if he accepts it as a Pewady-made answer because, by allowing someone else to make tile: decision for him, he is giving up his autonomy—-a neces— £3ar‘ycondition for a "scientific historian." This autonomous condition implies a broader definition (Df’ evidence which is the basis for today's philosophy of hiistory. Mautz and Sharaf provide such a definition: EI‘ History directs its attention to the interpretation and understanding of the past by studying the influences of events and developments on the organization and behavior of human groups. Its evidence con- sists of documents, relics, and the written recollections and impressions of people who 7 . Collingwood, op, c1t., p. 252 8 knew or thought they knew something about the period or event under study.8 Their definition of evidence is particularly important to this study because the author will utilize annual reports of corporations, interviews, where appropriate, books and periodical literature, court cases, legal documents and other appropriate evidential material in an effort to ascer- tain certain selective factors influencing the shift from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting report. Now that the question of what constitutes historical eVnidence for this study has been answered, the other question of’ how it is to be utilized must also be answered in order to urujerstand what is meant by the historical method and the pkuilosophy of history. As was stated earlier, a consensus dcxes not exist among historians as to the application of eVidence in historical research. Irving M. COpi contends that hiES‘torians must make use of hypotheses. For example, he states: Just as the biologist must use the method of science in formulating and testing his hypo- theses, so the historian must make hypotheses, too; Even those historians who seek to limit themselves to bare descriptions of past events must work with hypotheses. Those that believe historical research involves hypothe- SjJZing are few because the past has vanished, and ideas about it: cannot be verified like scientific hypotheses. Most believe historical research is inferential. To quote Collingwood: 8R. K. Mautz and Hussein A. Sharaf, The Philosophy of , American Accounting Association Monograph No. 6 Auditin (Hierican Accounting Association, 1961), p. 77. 9Irving M. Copi, Introduction to Logic (New York: The Ibcmillan Company, Second Edition, 1961), p. 46. 9 History has this in common with every other science: that the historian is not allowed to claim any single piece of knowl- edge, except where he can justify his claim by exhibiting to himself in the first place, and secondly to any one else who is both able and willing to follow his demonstra- tion, the grounds upon which it is based. Furthermore, there seems to be general agreement that the kind of knowledge obtained from inference or reasoning can only be ascertained with probability. For example Keynes states: Part of our knowledge we obtain direct, and part by argument. The Theory of Proba- bility is concerned with the part we obtained by argument,... In most branches of academic logic, such as the theory of syllogism or the geometry of ideal space, all the arguments aim at demon- strative certainty. They claim to be"con- clusive." But many other arguments are rational and claim some weight without pre- tending to be certain. In Metaphysics, in Science, and in Conduct, most of the arguments, upon which we habitually base our rational beliefs, are admitted to be inconclusive in a greater or lesser degree. Thus for a philos- Ophical treatment of these branches of knowledge, the study of probability is required.11 To summarize at this point it is worth stating that the Pfllifilosophy of history, denoting "the principiant consideration of'the meaning, the methods, and the canons of historical SC—i€ance," is reflective in the sense that the historian alfi?ives at conclusions following rules of inference and based uDon sufficient evidence to be persuasive to those who are Willing and able to follow his demonstration. For a complete 'Dhilosophy of history in which this study in the history of K 0 . . l Collingwood, op. c1t., p. 252. John Maynard Keynes, A Treatise on Probability (London: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 19H8), p. 3. 10 accounting thought can be constructed, it is necessary to consider the value of history. The Value of History Joseph Schumpeter's explanation of the value of history is particularly important in a philOSOphy of history because, as stated before, the three traditional philosophies imply that historical knowledge is impossible. Schumpeter believes that visits to the past have pedagogical value because those who teach from the most recent works will soon find themselves 1J1 difficulty unless these works have a minimum of historical :fiacts so that the student maygain an appropriate perspective, a 19erspective which helps provide a basis for making choices today.12 In addition, he thinks it necessary to study the hixstory of any subject because it gives an awareness of the Ilairure and speed of changing ideas within a discipline: We learn about both the futility and fertility of controversies; about detours, wasted efforts, and blind alleys; about spells of arrested growth, about our depen- dence upon chance, about how not to do things, and about leeways to make up for. We learn to understand why we are as far as ye actually are and also why we are not further. 3 In accounting the interaction of ideas and events make CThange a permanent feature. A knowledge of the nature and SEflaed of this change places us in a better position to under- SlLand our discipline's weaknesses and development through liime. Development of the forces shaping the change to the \ 12Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1961), p. 5 13Ibid., pp. 5—6. ll income statement can help us learn about those things in the above quotation. Further, such a knowledge can give us insights into possible improvements or alternatives to the income statement. The phiIOSOphy of history which was presented above portrayed history to be (a) a type of research designed to answer questions; (b) an attempt to discover actions of human beings that have occurred in the past; (c) a process by which evidence is interpreted; and, (d) a means whereby perspective could be provided for making choices today. The next section will.be concerned with some of the problems involved in organized historical inquiry . Some Problems in the Study of History The historian is subject to many limitations in con— Ciucrting his research. First, the raw materials at his evaluate. It is related to whether the historian should Ineuintain his own canons and values or should attempt to adhapt those of the people and the age with which he is con- cnezcned in formulating his judgments. Few question that in- fIDIPmed professional judgment, after a careful examination of flies evidence, is an important aspect of historical research. 3111: the resultant product of the historian is conditioned by irlifluences upon his judgment. Schumpeter contends that no Irlatter how hard we try to "cast off" those influences of our CNNTI environment we cannot succeed. Those who think they can aINe open to suspicion. Consequently, he recommends that our Véllues should be clearly stated in order that others will ncrt be misled.15 This writer agrees with Schumpeter's position. Conse- quently, the canons of "contemporary accounting theory" 1LiIbid., pp. 3-9 15Ibid., 13 will be utilized where appropriate, although it must be realized that some of the theories currently being advocated awe not generally accepted in accounting practice. There is a danger in evaluating the works of earlier wniters by the canons of modern day theory. Likewise, ‘Uuare also is a danger in ancestral worship. The former is aa common occurrence for those who regard earlier works as Inere rudimentary developments. On the other hand, the latrter is common for those who attempt to discover in past thexories an idea or concept in advance of its time. M. 131aug appropriately points out that, with a little training in (Serman philosophy, these two types of dangers resemble two polxar~opposite positions: "relativism and absolutism."16 The: relativist regards works of the past as a reflection of the: conditions of the times; the absolutist concentrates his effk>rts on the purely intellectual development in these earfiLier works in an effort to trace the progression from error to izruth in the development of his discipline. Further, Blatug states that few people ever held strictly either of thesue two extreme positions but can be placed somewhere on a CODTIinuum between the poles. The absolutist's position will essenntially be emphasized more in an effort to ascertain the relative importance of the various selective factors influ- encing the rise in the income statement. At the same time, hoWever, the relativist's position will not be discarded because, as Stated before, developments in accounting thought have 16M. Blaug, Economic Theopy in Retrospect (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1962), pp. 1-2. 1H traditionally been a function of accounting practice. Approaches to the Study of the History of Accounting Thought There are at least four approaches, all of which involve the interpretation of evidence, to a study in the history of accounting thought . The first approach would be to organize the study in tervns of the dominant theme during a specific period. For exeunple, as May suggests, accounting history could be divided intxb three periods according to the relative importance of the: forms of business enterprises: (a) individual ventures eitflier proprietorships or partnerships; (b) corporations with linrited liability and being owned and operated by few; (0) and the corporation of today with the separation of owners anti managers.17 This approach is rejected for the purposes Of"this dissertation because the last form, the corporation Witflu the separation of owners and managers, was operative thrmoughout most of the period in which the transition from the: balance sheet to the income statement occurred, at least the: external shift by creditors and stockholders. A second method would be to study the division of events int<> a chronological time sequence. An example of this ap- PrTMach can be found in an article by Lawrence Vance entitled "IT“? Authority of History in Inventory Valuation."l8 This 17George 0. May, Financial Accountipg,(New York: The Macmillan Company, 194?), p. 51. 18Lawrence Vance, "The Authority of History in Inventory Vaantion," Accounting Review, (July, 19H3), pp. 218-227. 15 approach is also rejected, except for the brief history of accounting presented in the next chapter, because it gen- erally does not focus attention upon underlying motives for accounting actions. Sequential time arrangement, although a necessary condition, should not be the basic object in a study in the history of accounting thought. A third approach would be to organize ones findings in such a way as to present a story. As mentioned earlier, examples of this approach are numerous in accounting. This approach has little value because emphasis is placed upon recreating the spectacle of the past rather than upon reasons behind accounting actions of the past. The last important possible approach is to determine the interrelationships between ideas and events, both en- dogenous and exogenous. Why did certain ideas originate? To what extent did events influence the development of these ideas? This approach is usually the best because it enables the researcher to relate the environment to changing ideas and concepts. It will be the approach generally followed in this study since the effects of environmental change provided the seeds that resulted in the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement. CHAPTER II GENERAL HISTORY OF FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING General In accounting today there exist many important and complex problems. Some of these problems are a result of the findings of current research such as the works of Chambers, Edwards and Bell, the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, the American Accounting Association, and many other persons and groups. These individuals and groups have created much controversy and Conflict within the profession not only by questioning conventional so—called "generally accepted accounting principles," but by their proposed alternatives. Another basic source of problems facing the accounting profession is the existence of certain ideas and practices "2 that are a result of the "conventional wisdom. In fact, lSee Raymond J. Chambers' concept of current cash equi- valent in Accounting, Evaluation and Economic Behavior, 1966, Prentice-Hall; the American Accounting AssociationTs recom— mendation of current cost data in A Statement of Basic Ac— counting Theory, 1966; The American Institute of Certified Public Accountants' Research Studies; Edwards and Bell's Theory and Measurement of Business Income, 1965, University of California Press. 2John Kenneth Galbraith, The Affluent Society (Boston, Massachusetts: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1958), Chapter II. A phrase coined by Professor Galbraith to mean ideas that are esteemed at any time for their acceptability. l6 17 it might be said that the conventional wisdom is the basis for many of the so—called "generally accepted accounting principles." One such problem has resulted from the apparent shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income state- ment as the primary accounting report. The balance sheet to— day is thought by many to be a collection of residuals instead of an accurate statement of a firm's financial position. That is, according to Robert T. Sprouse, the fundamental accounting equation of assets equals liabilities plus owners' equity has been drastically changed to: assets equal liabilities plus "what-you-may-call-its" plus owners' equity.3 As stated in Chapter I, a study in the history of accounting thought specifically concerned with the ascendancy of the income statement to the status once held by the balance sheet is the main topic of this dissertation. What were the underlying forces, both direct and indirect, that influenced this shift in emphasis? What were the contributions of various authors, professional associations, governmental laws and regu- lations, and other persons or groups to this shift? What events were important? Why did they occur? Answers to these and other questions are attempted in the pages ahead. It is hoped that these answers will help provide a better under- standing of the relative importance of the balance sheet and the income statement while demonstrating the fact that their existence is mutual and their properties interdependent. 3Robert T. Sprouse, "Accounting For What-You—May-Call- Its," Journal of Accountancy, (October, 1966), pp. H5—59. 18 Also, such answers can help provide a perspective which in turn can be utilized in analyzing the origins and nature of Sprouse's "what—you-may-call-its." But before this task of specifically documenting and presenting the most probable reasons for the ascendancy of the income statement is under— taken, it seems appropriate that a brief discussion of the development of financial accounting up to 1940, the time the shift was completed, be presented in order to gain a broad perspective for concrete accounting actions of the past. This brief summary of financial accounting will be presented from a chronological approach. Little attempt will be made to analyze the underlying motivations behind these past accounting actions. Yet, an attempt will be made to concentrate on those events that could have had an influence on the change in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement and will be further developed later in the dissertation. Financial Accounting: Pre-adamite Before Double Entry Accounting has a history extending back many centuries. In fact, there are even references to accountability for stewardship in the Bible.” There are other early records showing that piece-work rates and incentive bonus schemes 5 were discussed as early as 2,000 B. C. Next it might be 1+A. G. Donald, "Historical Background of Accounting as a Control," The Accounting Digest, Vol. XXXIII, (October, 1967), p. 19. 5 . Ibld. 19 worth mentioning the eleventh-century A. D. DomesdayyBook where an attempt was made to stocklist the assets of England in single-entry style.6 The point of interest in these early references is that people were held responsible for assets and thus rendered a periodic account, either oral or written, to a master. This periodic account could possibly be the origin of today's balance sheet and income statement. But the information available in these early periods is sketchy and fragmented, rendering evidential support to conclusions very tenuous, while supplying little to aid in the solving of today's problems. Thus, it is necessary to trace briefly the evolution of financial accounting based on the double entry system from Luca Pacioli's well known lugu book Summa de Arithmetics, Goemetrica, Proportioni et Prppor- tionalita. Period-From Pacioli to 1900 Pacioli's work is strikingly similar to what is found in today's textbooks. He instructed his readers to utilize three books: memorial, journal, and ledger. The memorial was a ,general book for recording all transactions of a business chronologically and in detail. Entries were then analyzed and transferred to the journal from the memorial. This recording first in the memorial and then in the journal was necessary because of the many coinage systems in use and because of the lack of original business papers. The journal was posted periodically to the ledger. The ledger contained a profit and loss account which reflected certain results from various 61bid., p. 19—20. 20 ventures. In addition, the ledger provided for the eventual transfer of the profit or loss to the capital account. Pacioli suggested that the practice was not wide spread. He also sug— gested that, before a new ledger was opened, a comparison of the equality of debits and credits be made similar to today's trial balance.7 The double-entry method, known as the Method of Venice, spread rapidly throughout most of Europe. But it wasn't until the industrial revolution of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries that it really flourished._ In fact, some have advo- cated, like Werner Sombart, that "systematic or scientific accounting, identified with the double-entry system, played an important part in releasing, activating, stimulating and accentuating the rationalistic pursuit of unlimited profit, an essential element in the capitalistic spirit."8 The above mentioned process of Pacioli whereby a com- parison of debits and credits in the old ledger was made before opening a new ledger, was, according to Littleton, later modified by including a so—called annual "balance account" in the ledger itself.9 This balance account had all the accounts in the old ledger transferred to it during the closing 7Pietro Grivalli, An Original Translation of the Treatise on Double-Entry (New York: Harper Brothers, Inc., 1911), p.100. 8Basil S. Yamey, "Accounting and the Rise of Capitalism: Further Notes on a Theme by Sombart," Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. II, No. 2, (Autumn, 196%), p. 117. 9A. C. Littleton, Accounting Evaluation to 1900 (New York: American Institute Publishing Company, Inc., 1933), pp. 127—130. 21 process. In short, all accounts with debit balances were credited and the balance account was debited, while all those with credit balances were debited and the balance account credited. Then the new ledger was Opened from the data con- tained in the balance account. Even though there exists no conclusive evidence, Littleton believes that these early balance accounts were c0pied out of the ledger and used as separate statements.10 Once statements were separated from the accounts, what— ever the reason, development was toward better arrangement of figures for clarity of factual material and toward refine- ments of classification to better reflect actual values. One of the earliest approaches to the modern arrangement according to Littleton appeared in 1788 in Introduction to Merchandise, ll by Hamilton. This book depicted the account form of the profit and loss sheet and the balance sheet which was to con- tinue in use throughout the nineteenth century, even though the beginnings of the so—called report form can also be traced to this early period. Early American and British thought did not concentrate on statement development probably because the proprietorship form of business organization existed where the owners were the managers and thus had access to the ledgers. But there were exceptions. George Soule's pioneering works were dis- tinctive achievements. His work on balance sheet construc- tion was the most comprehensive attempted between 1880 and 1900. lOIbid., p. 132. ll;p;g,, pp. 1H0—1u3. 22 For example, in addition to definite instructions for balance sheet preparation, which resembled present day columnar work— sheets found in principles texts, he considered the balance sheet to be of "particular service when the proprietor or some of the partners of a business reside in cities or places other than where the business is located, and it (balance sheet) is always more convenient for references and preser- vation than the books of the firm."12 The account form of statement presentation was also the general rule in nineteenth—century England and America. In fact, it was this form that was first to appear in published annual reports, as indicated by the 1895 annual report of General Electric, Illustration I, page 23. Patents and fran- chises probably appear first because of their size. The sub- traction of a mortgage from the corresponding asset was popular at the time. The inclusion of profit and loss figures on the asset side of the balance sheet seems highly unorthodox from today's standards. Nevertheless, it was the method of presenting deficits at this time. The arrangement of items from fixed to a current basis was also typical of this era. By the end of the nineteenth-century the form, especially of the balance sheet, had been basically established even though classification and subegroupings were crude. Subsequent developments were generally in the direction of refinements 12George Soule, Soule's New Science and Practice of Accounts (New Orleans, LOuisiana: unknown, seventh edition, “TY—1 03 , p. 57. 23 H ZOHH¢MHmDAAH xxxx xxxx IIII. NNMN ...............mm0A can uwwoum xxxx .................manwQ %chsm xxxx NNNN .Amucoanwwmcoo wceeafleaev..npueuuo madam u< xxxx ...............mo«u0uumm u< "moauOuao>:H xxxx .WMMM ..............mmmuwoum 6H xMOZ xxxx .oHnm>wouom moanouu< van mouoz xxxx ..........................nmmo xxxx Am a < moasvonum oomv meaom can execum xxxx xxxx MNMN ..............oHnm%mm mucsooo< NNHM ..........oumumm Hwom ponuo xxxx.mou=u:onoa no ummuoucH vosuuu< xxxx xxxx ....mou=u:opoa NNNM ......:oouo:u owmwuuoa moon aoasoo taco .ucou mom o>flm xxxx .zuao .M.z .wawvauam comavm xxxx "Amuawflm wcfiunuomm NNNM ...............vouuowoum Isamz cmnu nonuOV ouwumm Hmom xxxx ..................cOSEOU xxxx ..........mucme mafiMSuummncmz "xuOum kuanmo xxxx ........momwnu:uum can mucouwm mmHHHAHmI>. 2-14. ' 40 that a change was in the making. In addition, there were signs that the rise of the factory system would eventually require a new form of business organization—-the corporation. Particularly, the main signs were the huge capital invest- ments that were beginning to be needed and the increasing- ly competitive environment making survival tenuous at best. The Second Industrial Revolution The Industrial Revolution in about 1860 entered a new phase so different from what had preceded it that some his- torians call it the Second Industrial Revolution. The events which ushered in this new phase were mainly: (1) the Bessemer process for making steel; the perfection of the dynamo; and the invention of the internal combustion engine.5 These and other events resulted in the development of an industrial society based on technology, mass production, and mass mar— keting. In America a system based on partnerships or joint- stock companies emerged and has been called Industrial Capi- talism. The great industrial capitalists, like Andrew Carnegie, Samuel Slater, Philip Armour and Gordon McKay, were specialists of production rather than finance and followed a social code from the philosophy of Social Darwinism. This code held that economic life was, like biological life, the survival of the fittest. Professor Kroose's remarks about the industrial capitalist are particularly significant: Usually starting on a small scale, he raised most of his capital by plowing earnings back into his business. He despised financial mechanisms, 5Burns, op, cit., p. 643 41 such as balance sheets, income statements, and value based on earnings, and drew no distinction between the stockholder and the speculator.6 In the quest for increased supply of goods through the principle of survival of the fittest, the industrial capitalist naturally placed heavy emphasis on efficiency as measured by the volume of output (e. g. tons of steel). These men con— centrated on dynamic individuals placed in the right jobs and encouraging rivalries between managers and superintendents in an effort to squeeze even greater efforts. They generally did not believe in "evaluating a business on the basis of its earning power."7 Thus, they did not concentrate on income statement data or elaborate cost accounting systems. Never- theless, their emphasis on efficiency was to continue into the corporation and provide impetus for the forthcoming shift to income and expense data. The Rise of the Corporations By 1890 the state of technological progress and the ’growing consumer demand for mass—produced goods required large iamounts of capital. Furthermore, the bitterly competitive at- mosphere that the great industrial capitalists had created with their ruthless tactics resulted in a high bankruptcy rate and a high degree of insecurity among average businessmen. As a result, there was a need for a type of business organi- zation that would provide the necessary capital and yet reduce ¥ 6Herman E. Kroose, American Economic Development (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1962)p.275. 71bid., p. 276 42 the high degree of personal liability. The corporate form of business organization, although legally sanctioned much earlier,8 was ideally suited to ful— full these two needs through its stock ownership, limited liability, transferability of interests, and separation of owners and managers features. The new force generally con- sidered responsible for the initiation of this corporate revolution in America was the so-called financial capitalist9—— the banker, the investment banker, and the insurance company. The business policies of the financial capitalists were quite different from the:hmhstrial capitalists. They tended to spread their influence over many different industries in- stead of specializing in a single business. Consequently, the financial capitalists were instrumental in many reorganizations and consolidations. As a result, their interests were too diversified to permit them to undertake an active entre— preneurial role in the actual day-to—day decision—making of a business. Thus, managers were appointed to assume this func- tion. This delegation of authority to management eventually 8The first modern corporation law in the United States was passed by the Connecticut legislature in 1837, although New York State had passed a less modern version in 1811. In England the first modern corporation act was the British Com— panies Act in 1862, although a less compleuaact was passed in 1855. I. Pierpont Morgan was the chief representative of the new financial capitalists. For a good discussion of his ex- ploits see Lewis Corey, The House of Mopgan (New York: Grosset and Dunlap, Inc., 1930). For example, beibecame the head railroad financier in 1879 when he handled the sale of 250,000 Shares of New York Central stock; in 1892 he helped organize ‘the General Electric Company; in 1901 his capital conSolidated .firms producing sixty percent of the nation's steel into the LInited States Steel Corporation; also he was an important factor lDehind the establishment of American Telephone and Telegraph CkDmpany, International Harvester, as well as holding a con- ‘t1?011ing interest in a number of commercial banks, trust com— IDEinies and 1nsurance compan1es. 43 resulted in the emergence of a new force, the professional . 10 manager1a1 class. As one might eXpect, financial capitalists were more interested in financial policy than in any other aspect of business activity. They preferred corporate finance rather than industrial management as the following quotation reveals: Income statements and balance sheets, earnings per share, security prices, capitali- zation and security flotations interested them much more than the index of industrial produc- tion, the outppt of pig iron, or the volume of car loadings. Although the financial capitalists were important factors contributing to the internal shift in emphasis, as is obvious from their financial policies, it was the new pro- fessional managerial class resulting from the corporate form of business organization that was really important. The ascendancy of the professional manager, like all ,changes in business history, was not a revolutionary change. It took place gradually and reflected among other things the government's increasing economic influence as evidenced by the anti-trust legislation, the increasing importance of labor unions, and the public concern over the standard of 12 The most important factor, however, was the in- living. creasing complexity of the business enterprise itself. Stock- holders were becoming so numerous and businesses so large and complex that it became impracticable for the owners to both loE. A. Johnson and Herman E. Kroose, The American Econom (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice—Hall, Inc., IS60), pp. 250-254. 11 . Ibid., p. 251 l2Ibid., p. 261 44 control and operate their corporations. Thus it became feasible for a group of professionals, who were specialists, to make the necessary decisions. No single individual possessed the breath of knowledge or the time and energy to make all the decisions of a large corporation. In short, the directors of a large corporation had "to use accounting and statistics;' the management had to be departmentalized; and experts in each field became important?l3 Among other things, the two more important impacts on accounting thought and practice at first were the need to test the profitability of operations through the use of cost and revenue data by the professional managers and the emphasis on the balance sheet for external parties to meet the demands of the auditors, owners, and the financial capitalists, par- ticularly banks. This latter phenomenon, the emphasis on the balance sheet for external parties, was enhanced because of the widespread fear that legislation requiring the presen— tation of audited balance sheets, such as the Joint Stock Companies Act of 1862 in England, would also appear in the United States. For example, Section 94 of this British Act stated that the auditors must disclose "whether in their Opinion the balance sheet is a full and fair balance sheet."11+ On the other hand, there were no pressures demanding the dis- closure of income statement data in the early years of the corporate form of business organization. In fact, it was the l3lbid., pp. 262-263. lL'A. C. Littleton and V. K. Zimmerman, Accounting Theory: Continuity and Change (New Jersey: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1962), p. 106. 45 .general belief that profit and loss data were confidential information that could, if disclosed, aid competitors. As a result, income statements were seldom released that pro- vided any meaningful information. Evidence of the Internal Shift Development of Cost Accounting One of the most significant developments that provides evidential support for the internal shift in emphasis was the rapid emergence of cost accounting between 1885 and 1930. One of the earliest works in this area was Henry Metcalfe's Cost of Manufactures, published first in 1885. Although many of the ideas and techniques suggested by Metcalfe were not unknown, their integration into a unified costing system was a significant accomplishment because the beginnings of cost control for profit improvement were introduced.15 Two years after the first edition of Metcalfe's book appeared, two English practicing cost accounts, Garcke and Fells, published the first edition of their book Factory Accounts. Despite the fact that they introduced a scheme for showing the flow of cost through the firm that resembles to- day's method,16 the most striking innovation was their pro— cedure for integrating cost accounts with financial accounts in the general ledger. From this procedure it would be a simple task to use revenue accounts and those cost accounts lsS. Paul Garner, "Highlights in the Development of Cost Accounting", op2 cit., pp. 9-10. 168. Paul Garner, Evolution of Cost Accounting to 1925 (University, Alabama: University of Alabama Press, 1954), p.257. 46 for the calculation of profit and loss from Operation. American writers quickly espoused this idea of integra- ting cost and financial accounts. For example, John Whitmore was one such early writer. In expanding on a series of articles by A. Hamilton Church, Whitmore implied the new emphasis on profits in the following quotation from his series of articles: The fundamental principle is always the same, namely the principle of making a record sufficiently full to constitute a clear accounting for factory expenditure; and the object of the accounts is always the same1 namely, to elimiL nate waste from Operations. Furthermore, in commenting on the relationship of factory accounting to managerial organization he stated: The organization of a factory and its system of accounts and records are so closely allied, are so inseparable, that to talk of one is necessarily to talk of the other.18 Lastly, after detailing his cost system and the neces— sary journal entries to iintegrate it into the financial accounts, Whitmore explained: "profits are determined on the basis of these cost figures...giving thus the net result of "19 These quotations indicate it was recognized operations. that the integration of cost accounts into financial accounts made possible an improved method for calculating profit and loss through the matching of revenues and expenses. l7John Whitmore, "Factory Accounts as Applied to Machine Shops" The Journal of Accountancy, Vol. II (August, 1906), p. 249. l8, Ib1d., p. 345. lg;pid., Vol. III (November, 1906), p. 31 47 Other writers followed Whitmore's idea of account inte- _gration while stressing the importance of cost accounting for profit improVement through coSt control. ”For example, J. Lee Nicholson treated the matter at length in his 1909 Book Factory Organization and Costs, his 1913 book Cost Accounting-Theory and Practice, again in a book published in 1919 with J. D. Rohrback entitled Cost Accounting, and finally in 1923 in his book Profitable Management. Nichol- son's 1909 publication was important because he went to great lengths to specify what we would call today a cost center where costs were to be accumulated under the three main elements, direct labor, materials, and burden. But, most importantly, he introduced a system of distinguishing the sales for each division or department so that gross profit calculations could be made by division or department. The significance of this development is that it provides further evidence of the extent to which income statement data were being utilized internally. Nicholson in his 1913 work elaborated on the ideas and methods contained in his first book. Furthermore, he presented an elaborate pro- cedure for coordinating the cost and financial ledgers through the use of two reciprocal accounts.21 Although Nicholson's 1919 and 1923 books refined and elaborated his earlier publications, several quotations will indicate the importance accorded income and expense data. 20J. Lee Nicholson, Factory Organization and Costs (New York: Kohl Technical Publishing Company, 1909), pp. 31—33. 218. Paul Garner, Evolution, Op. cit., p. 271 48 Furthermore, these quotations also show that the integration of cost and financial accounts was complete. The former is illustrated when he stated: The methods of modern business have become exceedingly technical and complex. But their objective is easy to define-- it is control of the busineSS° and control is wanted to insure profits.2§ Account integration is suggested in the following: Cost accounting, as a science, is a branch of general accounting...With the cost books once established, the best modern usage is to incorporate their record in total in the general financial books. In this way the modern cost system builds up an inter- working series of accounts which furnish the basis for a detailed study of the Operations of a manufacturing business. Other American writers such as Frank E. Webner and C. E. Knoeppel, the engineer-accountant, were also espousing ideas and concepts similar to Nicholson. For example, Webner stated "the slogan of present-day industry is efficiency."2ur Furthermore, he also felt that cost accounts and general accounts should be integrated.25 C. E. Knoeppel stated in describing the relationship between accounting and engi- neering: Accounting and engineering are concerned with the same thing-—reducing costs--for only through a reduction of costs can larger profits 22J. Lee Nicholson, Profitable Management (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1923), preface. 23J. Lee Nicholson and John F. D. Rohrback, Cost Accountipg (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 19I9), p. 5 2L'Frank E. Webner, Factory Costs (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1911), p. 25. 251bid., p. 29. 49 or increased margin of sales be expected.2 Before leaving this section it is worth mentioning the cost convention, as Paton called it, that became a basic assumption in cost accounting. This convention is important because it became integrated into the matching concept as its characteristics indicate. A quotation from Gilman makes this point clear: This new subdivision of accounting (cost convention) was based upon a convention that costs could be transferred from one object to another, from one classification to another, and from one activity to another. Thus, the depreciation of a building operates as a transfer of value from the building itself to the materials in progress of manufacture, simultaneously lessening one value and in~ creasing another. This convention enables the cost account— ant to visualize a flow of values springing from expenditures of various types, through classified channels, finally attaching themselves to, and increasing the valuation of, the materials in process of manufacture. Direct labor and various other factory costs, such as rent, heat, light, property taxes, insurance, and supervision, came to be regarded as assets because they attach them- selves to materials in process. This convention is important because it attempted to show a direct relationship between specific items of income to specific items of cost-outlay. The lacking element for the matching concept was the identification of the items to specific time periods. 26C. E. Knoeppel, Organization and Administration (New York: Industrial Extension Institute, V01. 1, 1921), p. 245. 27Stephen Gilman, Accounting Concepts of Profit (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1939), p. 29. 50 Activities of the Scientific Management Engineers The activities of the so—called scientific-management engineers, although not a direCt indication of the shift by management to income statement data, provides indirect evi- dence of the new emphasis. This evidence is revealed through- out their writings because of the emphasis accorded efficency of operations, which in turn, implies an emphasis on profits. For example, Frederick W. Taylor, considered the father of scientific management, stated in one of his famous books: The principal object of management should be to secure the maximum prosperity for the employer, coupled with the maximum prosperity for each employee. Further, he used the words "maximum prosperity" in their broad sense to mean not only large dividends for a firm or owner, but the development of every branch of business to its highest state of excellence, so that prosperity may be per- manent. In his 1903 more technical book, Shop Management, Taylor, as a means of measuring efficiency, turned to or worked directly with cost accountants. Cost accounting techniques were used to compare the actual cost of an operation to its predeter— mined cost. This comparison was actually the beginning of standard costs where the difference between standard and actual cost could be used as a basis for investigating waste and in- efficiency. Taylor believed this method of measuring efficiency represented the principle of scientific management—-"knowing 8Frederick W. Taylor, The Principles of Scientific Management (London and New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1911), p. 9. i 29 . Ib1d. 51 exactly what you want men to do, and then seeing they do it in the best and cheapest way."30 Another famous American engineer, Henry L. Gantt, con- centrated his efforts on the matter of idle time and capacity by proposing that indirect expenses chargeable to output of the factory should bear the same ratio as those chargeable at normal capacity. In short, he was introducing what today is the notion of "normal" burden and predestined overhead rates. This emphasis on overhead costs and Taylor's use of elementary standard costing is important because it helped provide a means for a better matching of revenues and expenses. As a result, the utility of the income statement was enhanced. There were many other scientific management engineers whose efforts are indicative of the fact that an internal shift to profit and loss data had occurred. For the purposes of this study a reference to an article by C. Bertrand Thompson is sufficient to demonstrate this shift, even though these engineers were not specifically concerned with the ac- counting problems associated with the matching process. The development of the factory system brought with it many new problems connected with the organization and labor, the structure and equipment of factories, and the techniques of production. By successful manufactures these problems have always been solved in a way to make manufacturing at a profit possible. Early solutions, however, were necessarily crude and roughshod. With the enormous 1ncrease 30Frederick W. Taylor, Shop Management (New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 191177’p. 21. l Eldon S. Hendricksen, Accounting Theory (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965), pp. 30-31. 52 in demand for manufactured products, in the investment of capital, and the number of men engaged in business, with the consequent deve10pment of ever-keener.competition the early methods have been found insufficient. Especially within the last twenty years a degree of skill and technical training has been brought to bear upon the solution of factory problems which has made modern factory management much more elaborate, 32 refined, and effective than ever before. Evidence from Selected Firms Developments in cost accounting and the activities of the scientific management engineers provide a certain kind of documentation for the new emphasis because the techniques,' procedures, and theories proposed were all geared :at cost reduction for increased efficiency of Operations, which in turn, would hopefully result in increased profits. In essence, one might postulate that the most logical reason for these developments and activities was the increased demand for in- formation by management resulting from the rise of the cor- porate form of business organization and the changing com— petitive environment which evolved from the industrializa- tion of society. Even though the literature of the cost ac- counting and scientific management writers is highly sugges- tive of the internal shift in emphasis, it is not conclusive enough to conform with the requirements of "scientific" historical research as suggested in Chapter 1. Thus, as part of the research for this study an attempt was made to secure early internal income statements to ascertain whether income 32C. Bertrand Thompson, "The Literature of Scientific Management," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XXVII (1914), p. 506. 53 data were actually emphasized before the shift from the balance sheet to the income statement occurred for external parties in the early 1930's. The investigation conducted started with the selection of 45 businesses, shown in Illustration II, page 54, which were listed on the New York Stock Exchange on or before 1920 (25 were listed in 1912) and which still survive. No attempt *was made to select randomly the sample or to calculate its confidence limits. The governing factor was survival of the firm today so that the desired information could be more readily Obtained. On the other hand, companies were selected form various industries so that a cross section of data could be obtained in order to indicate the scope of internal state- ment used before 1930. Although a statistically testable sample was not drawn, the selection was appropriate because the number of corporations listed on the New York Stock Ex- change in 1920 or before was relatively small as compared to today. As a result a sample of 45 companies would, if sta- tistically verified, be more than enough to provide 95% to 98% confidence limits. The second step was to mail a copy of the letter shown in Illustration III, page 55, to the controllers of each of the previously listed 45 companies asking for internal income statements for a period before the external shift from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting report occurred during the early 1930's. Of the 45 companies, to whom the letters were mailed, nine did not reply at all and eight either stated that their records did not extend back, for some reason or another, to that era or their company's policy 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 54 ILLUSTRATION II LIST OF SELECTED COMPANIES Allied Chemical Corporation 23. Allis-Chalmers Company 24. American Can Company 25. American Ship Building Com- 26. pany American Smelting & Refining 27. Company 28. American Steel Foundries,Inc. 29. American Telephone & Telegraph Company 30. Anaconda Company 31. Armour and Company 32. B. F. Goodrich Company 33. Bethlehem Steel Corporation 34. Brunswick Corporation 35. Coca-Cola Company 36. Crucible Steel Company of 37. America 38. E. I. duPont deNemours and Company 39. Eastman Kodak Company 40. F. w. Woolworth Company 41. General Electric Company 42. General Motors Company 43. International Harvester Company 44. J. C. Penney Company, Inc. Kellogg Company 45. CONTACTED Kennecott Corporation Liggett 6 Myers Tobacco,Inc. National Biscuit Company National Steel Corpora- tion New York Air Brake Company Otis Elevator Company Owens-Illinois Phelps Dodge Corporation Procter & Gamble Company Pullman Incorporated P. Lorillard Company Remington Office Equipment Republic Steel Company S. S. Kresge Company Sears Roebuck & Company Sinclair Oil Corporation Standard Oil Company (N.J.) Uniroyal (U.S. Rubber) United Fruit Company United States Envelope Company United States Steel Cor— poration Westinghouse Electric Company White Motor Corporation 55 ILLUSTRATION III SAMPLE COPY OF LETTER MAILED TO 45 SELECTED COMPANIES October 30, 1967 Mr. James Jones Vice-President and Comptroller XYZ Corporation 1690 Erie Road Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15230 Dear Mr. Jones: As a Doctor of PhilosOphy candidate in Accounting I am doing my dissertation in the area of the history of accounting thought. Specifically, this study will be concerned with the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income state- ment as the primary accounting report. Since the XYZ corporation was a pioneer in the development of annual reporting to stockholders, your old statements are an invaluable aid. However, it seems necessary to ascertain whether or not an elaborate income statement was prepared internally, as Opposed to the condensed version for external reporting, before the shift in emphasis occurred during the early 1930's. If there were elaborate income statements prepared at this time I would very much appreciate a copy of one or visit your company to examine them if they are un- available. Thank you for your anticipated co-Operation. Sincerely yours, Clifford D. Brown Doctoral Candidate Michigan State University CDB/ceb 56 did not permit them to divulge such information. The re— maining twenty-eight companies that did reply sent copies of early internal income statements, disclosed their nature in a letter, or included combinations of both. Upon analyzing these internal statements and letters it was concluded that income statement data were highly sig- nificant for internal management long before the shift in emphasis occurred for external parties, such as investors and creditors. These statements and letters do not, however, specifically document a shift from balance sheet data to in- come statement data by internal management. They simply suggested that no shift occurred internally during the early 1930's, the time that, as will be shown later in this chapter, it occurred in the minds of external parties. This latter suggestion is particularly important to this dissertation, even though as was detailed earlier in this chapter or an earlier chapter there is reason to believe that the rise of the corporation in response to the changing economic scene resulted in the increased emphasis on profit and loss data by internal management between 1890 and 1930. A documentation of the fact that profit and loss data were extensively used by management before 1930 is sufficient evidence to conclude that the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement in the 1930's as the primary accounting report was an external shift only. On the other hand, this conclusion does not preclude one from suggesting that the external shift did not have an impact on internal accounting. To be sure, the refinement of the matching concept and the resulting 57 principles underlying the preparation of financial statements that resulted from this new external emphasis on the income statement affected internal accounting by providing better techniques and methods for the assembly and communication of more relevant and timely information. Some selected quotations and examples from these replies will now be presented in support of the above conclusion. Mr. John N. Hart, Vice-President and Controller of the B. F. Goodrich Company in his letter of November 28, 1967 made the following statement: The shift in emphasis, which you are con- cerned with, is a shift made by creditors and stockholders who are outside the business as compared to internal operating people who are concerned with the day—to-day problems of production and sales. Furthermore, he stated in reference to internal balance sheets prior to 1930 "that very few operating personnel below the senior corporate executive received balance sheets." On the other hand, in reference to internal income statements of this early era he stated that they "varied in degree of 'elaborateness' depending upon the level of management to which they were furnished." Mr. G. D. Dearlove, Assistant Comptroller of International Harvester Company in commenting on his company's internal in- come statements prior to 1930 stated: While there have been changes in phi— losophy and improvements in format over the years, internal income statements of the Company have always been in sufficient detail to provide adequate information for internal management purposes and, therefore, of neces- sity, have generally been more complete than statements appropriate for external reporting. 58 Mr. Fillmore B. Eisenberg, Vice-President and Controller of the Coca-Cola Company wrote regarding the form of his company's internal income statement prior to the 1930's the following: ....for internal management purposes we have always prepared more detailed statements than those published in the annual reports to stockholders. Over the years these statements have taken various forms and emphasis has been directed to different areas depending on the nature of conditions and problems extant at the time, since as you know our Company has deveIOped greatly and in many directions over its long history. Our objective with regard to internal management statements has always been to supply operating managers with suf- ficient detail, either in the income state- ments, or as supporting schedules to allow them to have a comprehensive picture of cur— rent operations. Such information would in general consist of sales, both dollars and units of product, details of manufacturing expenses and other cost of sales items and details of various operating expenses. Mr. Charles C. Link, Jr., Assistant Comptroller of American Smelting and Refining Company wrote the following in reference to his company's internal income statements before 1930: In connection with your recent letter concerning income statements prior to the 1930's, you are correct in your assumption that ASARCO prepared for internal use a more detailed income statement than that used in its external reporting. Basically, the Company philosophy has always been oriented toward reporting earnings by .management responsibility. Each plant or mine is treated as an individual profit center, and an individual profit and loss statement is prepared by each (generally on a monthly basis). This was true even before 1930. The internal income statement before 1930 included three main groups: smelting and refining plants, mines, and all other items. Each plant and mine was listed and the total earnings of 59 each group reported- The plants were the respOnsibility of the Vice-President in charge of Smelting and Refining, while the mines were the responsibility of the Vice- President in the Mining Department. Each of these vice-presidents had group mana- gers in turn responsible for certain sub- 'divisions (Mexican smelters, Mexican mines, Southwestern Mining Departments, etc.) The "all other items," which were small in number, were the responsibility of other Company officials although not then important enough to be reported in sub-groups. This early basic system is still in use today, but it has been expanded to reflect larger volume of business and the importance of additional activities now performed by the Company. Mr. N. E. Jones, Associate Comptroller of the Procter and Gamble Company in commenting on his company's income statements prepared for internal use prior to 1930 wrote: Income statements prepared for internal use prior to 1930 were just as elaborate and detailed as those prepared after the shift in emphasis occurred during the early 1930's. Our perusal of the available internal records in the 20's and 30's shows no shift in emphasis or detail. The change which occurred was an external change. 5 An executive of a large steel company answered in his letter as follows: In both the period prior to the early 1930's and the current period there are detailed supporting statements for internal use-~many more now than in the early period due to the decentralization of management and the general trend to responsibility accounting at all levels. The availability of data processing equipment serves these needs but additiOnally provides more detail which could not have been provided under the essentially manual techniques employed in the earlier years. Mr. E. A. Bescherer, Specialist——General Accounting Research, of the General Electric Company stated in his reply: 60 A review of our reports at that time indicates that there were more elaborate reports prepared internally from at least the mid-1900's. For example, for 1930 a statement was prepared which analyzed operating results down through "Profits available for dividends" by major segments of the business. In addition, there were more detailed breakdowns of a number of the items, such as "Income from other sources," shown in the published statements. This statement by Mr. Bescherer is supported and documented in a series of three books entitled General Electric's Growth, General Electric's Organization, and The Work of a Professional Manager copyrighted by the General Electric Company under the title Professional Management in General Electric.33 The Assistant Controller, F. G. Saviers of Westinghouse Electric Corporation stated in his reply that "in the year 1928 the corporate statement (income) included considerably more detail than that which was published in the Annual Re— port." To verify this he included a COpy of the income state- ment as published in the Annual Report of 1928, and a copy of the internal income statement for the same year. These state- ments are reproduced as Illustrations IV page 61 and Illus- tration V page 62 respectively. Furthermore, he felt that "there were many detailed statements prepared for internal use for such items of expense as distribution, administration, and etc." even though, in accordance with company policy, these detailed statements were not retained. At a glance, one of the significant features of the internal income statement 3See for example Chapter Two, Evolution of Organization, in Book One, General Electric's Growth (United States of America: General Electric Company, 1953), pp. 23—58. 61 ILLUSTRATION IV WESTINGHOUSE ELECTRIC STATEMENT OF CONSOLIDATED INCOME AND PROFIT & LOSS FOR THE YEAR ENDED MARCH 31, 1928 Gross Earnings: Sales Billed Cost of Sales: Factory Cost, including depreciation of Property and Plant and all Distribution, Administration and General Expenses; and Taxes ............................... Net Manufacturing Profit Other Income: Interest, Discount and Miscellaneous In- come and Profits..................... Dividends and Interest on Sundry Stocks and Bonds Owned ..................... Gross Income From All Sources Deductions from Income: Interest Charges...................... Net Income for the Year ................. Dividends on Preferred and Common Stocks. Surplus for the Year .................... Surplus, March 31, 1927.................. Gross Surplus............................ Adjustments: Reserves for possible adjustments of book values of Investments in Affiliated Companies, Accounts Receivable and Miscellaneous Charges, of certain Investments............... Patents, Charters, Franchises, Etc., written down to nominal value........ Total......... Less balance of Reserve previously appropriated for Federal Income Taxes, not required......................... Surplus, March 31, 1928, Per Balance Sheet. for Pensions and for Notes and less profit realized on the sale XXXX XXX}! XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXX)! XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX 62 ILLUSTRATION V WESTINGHOUSE ELECTRIC COMPARATIVE STATEMENT OF OPERATIONS FOR THE PERIOD ENDED MARCH 31, 1928 Net sales billed ......................... Cost of sales billed...................... Per cent of net sales billed........... Manufacturing profit...................... General expenses: Distribution........................... Administration......................... Total........... Gross operating profit.................... Per cent of net sales billed........... Other charges against operations.......... Miscellaneous charges.................. Standard development-Unapplied......... Total........... Net operating profit...................... Per cent of net sales billed........... Other income: From investments....................... Dividends-Other proprietary compan1es.. Interest and discount.................. Royalties.............................. Miscellaneous.......................... Total........... Gross income (Line 13 plus 20)............ Deductions from income: Interest charges....................... Federal taxes accrued and miscellaneous Total........... Net income............................. Surplus adjustments, net.................. Inter-manufacturing company dividends..... Surplus for period........................ Surplus beginning of period............... Surplus available for dividends and other purposes................................. Dividends on capital stock: Preferred stock........................ Common stock........................... Total.......... Surplus end of period..................... XXXX XXXX ‘XXXX XXXX XX XX XX XX XXXX XXXX XXXX XX XX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XX XX XX XX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX 63 or the Comparative Statement of Operations as it is called, was the separation of Manufacturing Profit expressed both in dollars and as percentages of net sales billed. On the other hand, in the published statement of Consolidated Income and Profit and Loss, these items were included in one figure, the Cost of Sales, leaving a Net Manufacturing Profit balance. These alternative treatments suggest the importance given to profit and loss data for internal purposes as Opposed to the condensed version for external purposes prior to the occurrence of the so-called shift in emphasis in the early 1930's. Allied Chemical Corporation's Assistant Comptroller, Mr. F. L. Linton, stated in his reply that: Allied Chemical was organized in 1920 by the alliance of five companies which subsequently became operating divisions. The income statements prepared for the managements of these companies and the consolidated income statement were much more detailed than the published condensed version. Another major supporting schedule presented sales quantities, sales dollars, cost of sales and ‘gross profit by major products or major product pgroups. Furthermore, he included selected copies of his company's old methods bulletin which show the composition of the internal income statement and the major supporting schedules of ex- penses which were used prior to the 1930's. These copies are shown in Illustration VI, pages 64, 65, 66, and 67. From the detail of the items under income and surplus classification, the list of manufacturing cost controlling accounts, selling expense classification, and the general administration expense one is led to believe that profit and loss data were exten-- sively utilized for both planning and controlling of operations 64 ILLUSTRATION VI ALLIED CHEMICAL & DYE CORPORATION Methods Bulletin in Use Before 1930 Sales Sales - Domestic Sales - Export-Direct and Foreign (102) Sales - Export - Direct (103) Sales - Export - Foreign Branches Total Sales Discounts Sales - Net Cost of Sales Gross Profit Deductions from Gross Profit Selling Expense General Administration Expense Freight Car Operations - Net Marine Equipment Operations- Net Idle Plant Expense Miscellaneous Other Deductions Qperating Profit Other Income Interest Dividends Commissions and Brokerage - Net Operating Contracts - Net Discount on Purchases Barrett Building and Other Rentals - Net (120) Rentals - Net (122) Barrett Building Company - Net Other Income (Continued) Miscellaneous Engineering and Other. Services Rendered - Net Tully Farms Operations Gross Income Deductions from Gross Income Federal and Canadian Income Taxes (126) Federal Income Taxes (127) Canadian Income Taxes Interest (128) Interest on Funded Debt (129) Other Interest Bad Debts Reserve Miscellaneous (130) Minority Interests Net Income Surplus at Beginning Surplus Adjustment Surplus Adjustment - Credit Surplus Adjustment - Debit Deductions from Surplus, Etc. Dividends — Preferred Dividends - Common Surplus - Balance Sheet 65 ILLUSTRATION VI - continued LIST OF MANUFACTURING COST CONTROLLING ACCOUNTS Raw and Productive Materials Consumed Productive Labor Manufacturing Expense Fuel Manufacturing Supplies Maintenance Power Plant Transportation Warehousing Tests and Inspection Research and Development Plant Administration Depreciation Dismantling and Retirements Insurance - Other Than Fire Insurance - Fire Taxes Other Manufacturing Expenses By-Products, Residuals, Etc. ILLUSTRATION VI - continued ALLIED CHEMICAL & DYE CORPORATION Selling Expense Classification Showing the Grouping of Selling Expense Accounts. Classification Salaries: Managers and Salesmen Office Employees Warehouse Employees Mixing Department Employees Laboratory Employees Other Employees Expenses of Employees: Managers and Salesmen Other Employees Office OperatinggExpense: Supplies & Incid. Exp., Office, the., etc. Supplies & Incid. Exp., Laboratory Stationery and Printing Postage Telephone, Telegraph and Cable Light, Heat and Power Buildipg and Equipment Expense: Repairs and Renewals - Buildings Repairs and Renewals - Office Equipment Repairs and Renewals - Other Equipment Depreciation - Bldgs., & Office & Other Equipment Rent of Offices & Bldgs. Brokerage Storage Advertising: Samples Advertising Newspapers, Period- icals and Exhibits Circulars, Catalogues,etc. Classification ContainerspiPackages, Packing Material, Etc. Freight and Express: Freight and Express - Inward Freight and Express - Outward Trucking and Drayage: Trucking Employees Supplies and Expenses Repairs & Renewals - Trucking Depreciation - Trucking Insurance - Trucking Taxes - Trucking Drayage Insurance and Taxes: Insurance - Other Taxes - Other Other Expenses: Bank Exchange and Collection Fees Profit and Loss on Foreign Exchange Bad Debts Collection Expenses Amortization of Lease- hold Expenditures Export Charges Custom Duties Barrett Specification Inspection Other Expenses ILLUSTRATION 67 VI - continued ALLIED CHEMICAL & DYE CORPORATION General Administration Expense Classification Showing the Grouping of General Administration Expense Accounts. Classification Salaries: Officials and Department Heads Clerks and Attendants Engineers Chemists Office Building Employees Expenses of Employees: Transportation and Pullman Fares Other Expenses Entertainment Law Expenses and Special Services: Trademark and Patent Expense Law Expense Law EXpense Special Services Special Services Office Operating Expense: Stationery and Printing Telephone, Telegraph and Cable Service Postage Incidental Expense Light, Heat and Power Office Supplies Classification Building and Equipment Expenses: Rent of Offices and Buildings Depreciation of Buildings Depreciation of Equipment Amortization of Lease- hold Expenditures Repairs and Renewals - Equipment Repairs and Renewals - Buildings Rental of Office Equipment Contributions, Subscriptions and Membership_; Selling Expense General Administration Expense Insurance and Taxes: Fire Insurance Employer's Liability Insurance Other Insurance State Income Taxes, Other Taxes Pensions Other Expenses: Domestic Exchange Foreign Exchange - Net Royalties Other Expenses 68 before the 1930's. Thus, as with the preceeding examples, no significant shift from the balance sheet to the income statement internally occurred during the 1930's. The Comptroller, T. A. Murphy, of the General Motors Corporation likewise stated in his reply the following: The scope of internal income reporting has not changed appreciably since the early 1920's. We have, of course, made improvements in reporting techniques but, for the most part, these improvements have principally tended to reduce the great volume of data which formerly was reported to management in order to tell the financial story in as concise a manner as pos- sible. Significant financial reports which were prepared in this early period, as well as today, included the forecast income statement and financial budgets. These financial tools, which are commonplace now with most companies, were not so widely used by other concerns at that time. However, in General Motors, it could be fairly stated that increasing emphasis has been placed on forward estimates rather than historical data. As to our published financial statements, you may also find it interesting to note that since 1923 the income statement has preceded the balance sheet in the annual report to the stock- holders of the Corporation. The above statement by Mr. T. A. Murphy can further be verified by reference to the famous work of the late Alfred P. Sloan, Jr., former chairman of the Board of Directors of General Motors. For example, he stated that since the early 1920's "the basic elements of financial control in General Motors are cost, price, "3” These items, as is volume, and rate of return on investment. well known, depend upon accurate and timely profit and loss data. The next reference to be submitted in support of the aforementioned.conclusions was supplied by Mr. R. Leopold, Super- vising Accountant, of American Telephone and Telegraph Company. 3”Alfred P. Sloan, Jr., My Years With General Motors (Garden City, New York: Doubleday and Company,Inc.,196H), p. 1H0. 69 Illustration VII page 70 shows a comparative internal income statement for 1907. Illustration VIII page 71 shows a com- parative external earnings statement for 1907. These two illustrations also indicate the greater detail accorded items in the internal income statement. For example, expenses were listed separately for internal purposes, whereas, only one figure was presented in the internal statement. The last, but certainly not the least, evidential support that will be presented consists of an interview with Mr. W. Dean Reed, Assistant Comptroller of Owens-Illinois Corporation. During the course of the interview selected internal income statements from 1907, the beginning of the company, until 1990 period were reviewed. The format of the income statement did not change appreciably during the period examined, except to accommodate the changing scope of operations. If anything, the complexity of these early statements was reduced between 1907 and 1990. This reduction was the result of two forces. First of all, as more modern technology was applied to account- ing methods and procedures the centralization of accounting functions became possible. For example, the accounts receivable, accounts payable and payroll records were consolidated and no longer a task for individual plants. Secondly, the reorganization of the company into separate Operating divisions, along with the development of cost centers and re8ponsibility accounting, re— sulted in a reduction in the complexity of company and plant- wide internal income statements even though the complexity and frequency of lower level supporting reports were increased. The significant point, as the above evidence reveals, in U.S. 7O ILLUSTRATION VII AMERICAN TELEPHONE AND TELEGRAPH COMPANY Combined Earnings and Expenses All Bell Operating Companies Including American Telephone and Telegraph Company. (Instrument rental and other duplications excluded). GROSS EARNINGS 1906 1907 Increase Exchange service xxxx xxxx xxxx Toll service xxxx xxxx xxxx Total telephone earnings xxxx xxxx xxxx Private line service xxxx xxxx xxxx Sub-licensee service xxxx xxxx xxxx Messenger xxxx xxxx xxxx Real estate xxxx xxxx xxxx Dividends & interest xxxx xxxx xxxx Miscellaneous xxxx xxxx xxxx Total other earnings xxxx xxxx xxxx Total gross earnings xxxx xxxx xxxx EXPENSES General xxxx xxxx xxxx Operating xxxx xxxx xxxx Maintenance xxxx xxxx xxxx Total telephone expenses xxxx xxxx xxxx Private line xxxx xxxx xxxx Sub-license xxxx xxxx xxxx Messenger xxxx xxxx xxxx Real estate xxxx xxxx xxxx Miscellaneous xxxx xxxx xxxx Total other expenses xxxx xxxx xxxx Total expenses (except int. xxxx xxxx xxxx NET EARNINGS Deduct interest balance xxxx xxxx xxxx xxxx xxxx xxxx Dividends declared by licensee companies xxxx xxxx xxxx By A. T. & T. Co. xxxx xxxx xxxx Total dividends xxxx xxxx xxxx Deduct dividends received by A.T.&T.Co. from licen- see companies xxxx xxxx xxxx Dividends (duplications excluded) xxxx xxxx xxxx Undivided profits xxxx xxxx xxxx AMERICAN 71 ILLUSTRATION VIII TELEPHONE AND TELEGRAPH COMPANY Comparative Statement of Earnings and Expenses EARNINGS: D1v1dend800...OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Interest and other revenue from associated and licensed companies.................. Telephone Traffic (net)...... Real Estate............. Other Sources... EXPENSES.......... NET EARNINGS...... Deduct Interest... Dividends Paid.... Balance... Carried to Reserves...... Carried to Surplus....... 1906 XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX 1907 XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX XXXX 72 is there was no shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting report for managerial use. The latter report, it was felt by Mr. Reed, was always the prime report throughout his company's history. Summary This chapter was concerned with the new emphasis on profit and loss data by internal management of a firm that generally appeared between 1885 and 1930. A long chain of ideas and events were presented that eventually culminated with income data being considered of upmost importance to a successful evaluation of a company's operations as a guide to future action. The beginning force that set this chain of ideas and events into motion was the numerous inventions that appeared in England shortly after 1750, even though they were them- selves the result of many complex and remote causes. These inventions helped pave the way for the industrialization of society through the use of the factory system. Even though old forms of business organization, particularly the sole proprietorship, still dominated at the outset, the increasing need for huge amounts of capital was beginning to be felt. This need was accentuated by a series of inventions around 1860: (l) the Bessemer process, (2) the perfection of the dynamo, (3) the internal combustion engine. The original reaction to these new inventions and econo- mic circumstances was the emergence of what has been called industrial capitalism, based on the partnership or joint- stock company form of business organization. The industrial capitalists despised financial statements. Yet his tactics 73 of cut-throat competition and emphasis on efficiency created an industrial community where investment requirements were tremendous and survival very tenuous. Thus, conditions were ripe for a type of business organization that could provide the necessary capital and yet reduce the high degree of per- sonal liability. As a result, the corporate form of business organization, through the help of the so-called financial capitalist, became popular. The financial capitalists tended to spread their in- terests over many businesses and were instrumental in many reorganizations and consolidations. As a result, managers were appointed to assume the function of operating the business. A new managerial class developed which found it necessary to use accounting and related statistics in its decisions be— cause no single individual possessed the breath of knowledge or the time or energy to make all the decisions. Income and expense data for the purpose of testing the profitability of operations as a guide to future action became an integral part of the accounting data required by these professional managers. On the other hand, balance sheet data were still considered the more important to the financial capitalist and other ex- ternal parties. The last topic presented as evidence of this internal shift in emphasis was reference to the works of the cost account— ants and scientific management writers. Furthermore, reference was made to certain replies from various corporations which indicated that income and expense data were highly significant for internal purposes long before the external shift in em- phasis occurred in the early 1930's. CHAPTER IV THE EXTERNAL SHIFT FROM THE BALANCE SHEET TO THE INCOME STATEMENT General In Chapter II, and again in Chapter III it was suggest- ed that developments in British and American law and auditing were major factors tending to preserve the balance sheet in a position of prominence over the income statement as the primary external financial report until well into the 19308. For example, the Joint Stock Companies Act of 1894 in Britain required the presentation of a "full and fair" balance sheet to the stockholders but did not even suggest than an income statement be presented. Furthermore, it was also stated that this policy was continued in Section 99 of the 1862 Act when it stated that the auditors must disclose "whether in their opinion the balance sheet is a full and fair balance sheet." Although in the United States similar legislation did not appear, the rise of financial capitalism and the emer- .gence of the so-called balance sheet audit produced the same effect. But this prominence did not last. In fact the in— come statement eventually superseded the balance sheet in terms of importance to external parties. By 1934 the impact 79 75 of this changing emphasis can even be found in publications of the American Institute of Accountants. For example, in its 1939 statement entitled "Audit of Corporate Accounts" the following passage appeared: The earning capacity is the fact of crucial importance in the valuation of an industrial enterprise, and therefore the income account is usually far more impor— tant than the balance sheet. Furthermore, by 1990 the shift to the income statement was almost entirely complete in the minds of external parties like stockholders and creditors. George 0. May stressed this fact when he wrote in the May, 1937 issue of the Journal of Accountancy that the determination of income "is now generally recognized as the most important problem in the field of finan- cial accounting."2 The next section will be concerned with a documentation of this external shift. Documentation of the External Shift from the Balance Sheet to the Income Statement In Accounting Textbooks In 1908 Sprague wrote: "The balance sheet may be consider- ed the groundwork of all accountancy, the origin and terminus n3 of every account. Likewise, Henry Rand Hatfield in his 1909 book Modern Accounting contended that the balance sheet is the 1American Institute of Accountants, Audit of Corporate Accounts (New York: American Institute of Accountants, 1939),p.10. 2George 0. May, "Improvement in Financial Accounts? The Journal of Accountangy, (May, 1937), p. 396. 3Charles E. Sprague, The Philosophy of Accounts (New York: The Ronald Press, 1908), p. 26. 76 goal of all accounting.Ur Roy B. Kester in his book Account- ing Theory and Practice also maintained a similar belief.5 As time went on these authors tended to alter their views with respect to the importance of the balance sheet. For example, Hatfield wrote in his 1929 principles book, in commenting on the changes in the field of accounting since his above mentioned 1909 publication, the following: Accounting is essentially of a twofold character. It seeks to disclose the facts regarding the amount and kind of assets and liabilities. In addition to this and of equal if not superior importance, is the information which it gives in regard to the proprietorship, and the various causes which have contributed to this result. The showing of assets is the main function of the balance sheet... The exhibit of the changes in proprietorship is embodied in an income or profit and loss state- ment. Each of these statements has its own value and use.6 Kester in his 1922 revision of his aforementioned 1917 book essentially continued the view of the importance of the balance sheet as the most useful statement, particularly for credit purposes. But in the third revised edition in 1930 he wrote: The two basic problems of accounting are concerned with the determination of: (1) the worth or proprietorship of a business at a given time; and (2) the success or failure of a business endeavor during a given or definite period of time. . L'Henry Rand Hatfield, Modern Accounting (New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1909), p. 3—9. 5Roy B. Kester, Accounting Theory and Practice (New York: The Ronald Press Co., 19177, Chapter 1. 6Henry Rand Hatfield, Accounting: Its Principles and Problems (New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1929), p. 290. 7Roy B. Kester, Accounting Theory and Practice,op. cit., (1930 edition, Vol. 1), p. 35. 77 From here Kester then went to great lengths to explain that profit is a part of prOprietorship in the accounting equation of asset—liabilities = proprietorship. In addition he empha— sizes the balance sheet approach for the calculation of in- come even though it is to management's advantage "to maintain the proper relationship between income and expense," implying the matching process.8 The fourth revised edition of 1939 has some notable changes that indicate how Kester viewed the changing emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement. These changes were criticisms of current balance sheet constructions and the use of a new profit equation to introduce the matching con— cept of income-costs = profit.9 The criticisms of the balance sheet related to the problem of datum content and value con— tent necessary for a clear financial condition.10 Other less theoretical textbooks also indicate the shift in emphasis that occurred. In principles text written by Mo Kinsey, later by Mc Kinsey and Noble, subsequently by Noble, then Noble and Niswonger, and currently by Niswonger and Fess, this change is also reflected. The first edition of 1929 considered the balance sheet as "one of the most important statements that the proprietor receives."ll 8Ibid., p. 39. 91bid., 1939 edition, p. 36. lOIbid., pp. 26-27. 11James 0. Mc Kinsey, Accounting Principles (Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Co., 1929), p. 21. 78 This statement was repeated in the 1935 edition12 and the 13 But it was omitted in the fourth edition in 1939 edition. describing the importance of the balance sheet. Instead, the essence of this above quoted statement was ascribed to the income statement as follows: "The amount of profit or loss incurred during a given period is the most important single fact of the period."ll‘l In addition, the transactions approach, rather than the capital maintenance approach, to income de- termination was now emphasized for the first time. Robert H. Montgomery, although the champion of the balance sheet audit for many years, also reflected the in- creased importance of the income statement in the later edi- tions of his famous book Auditing Theory and Practice. For example, in his first edition of 1912 he stated that "where there is an audit department properly conducted, or where the purpose of the examination is to determine the net worth of the concern, the auditor will usually confine himself entirely to the items of the balance sheet."15 This view continued even in his 1939 edition as others were recom- mending the use of the term financial statements and em- phasizing the importance of the income statement. The 12James 0. Mc Kinsey and Howard S. Noble, Accounting Principles (Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Co., second edition, 1935), p. 15. 13 Ibid., 1939 edition, p. 7. 1L'Howard S. Noble, Accounting Principles (Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Co., fourth edition, 1995), p. 91. 15Robert H. Montgomery, Auditing Theory and Practice (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1912), p. 72. 79 following quotation indicates this view: The importance of the balance sheet not only as the ultimate goal in the conduct of an audit but also as a basis for the determination of audit procedure, warrants attention.16 Furthermore, the income account was still being treated as a supplement to the balance sheet, although he admits that . . . . . . 17 an audit 18 not completed until it also 18 examined. The 1990 sixth revision contained some changes over its predecessor editions, reflecting among other things the change in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income state— ment, the pronouncements of the American Institute of Account- ants, the American Accounting Association, and the SEC. Most notable was the use of the term financial statements in refer- ence to the extend of the audit and the introduction of the short form audit report. But he still has a yearning for the good "old" balance sheet prominence as is evidenced by the following passage: In recent years great stress has been laid on the importance of the income statement to an understanding by investors and others of the financial affairs of a corporation. It is said that the value of a business, and consequently of its assets, depends almost entirely on its earning power. Because of this feeling, there has been a tendency to belittle the balance sheet as a source of information, and to view the accounting problems largely from the point of view of the income statement ... however, the balance sheet also has information for the intelli— gent reader which, in some circumstances at least, is of equal importance to that displayed in the income statement. 16Ibid., 1939 edition, p. 78. 17Ibid., p. 956. 18Ibid., 1990 edition, p. 59. 80 Many other works could be cited as evidence of the shift from the balance sheet to the income statement. But the point is clear that the groundwork for the shift was laid in the 1920's, accentuated in the 1930's and completed by 1990. The next section will be concerned with this shift as it evolved in corporate annual reports. In Financial Reports of Corporations A brief survey of some of the older published annual reports, shown in Illustration IX, page 81, reveals that there was a gradual emergence, not a sudden or dramatic appearance, of the presentation of income statement data as they are reported today. Furthermore, it seemed apparent that there was significant decline in the complexity of the balance sheet. In fact, the contrary was observed, that is balance sheets became more and more complete and informative in terms of today's standards. But the important point is that income information in early reports either was nonexistent or con- sisted of a simple T account copied from the ledger, whereas, the balance sheet was the main center of attraction. This situation changed over the years until, by 1950, 18 of the 20 companies examined displayed modern type income statements. Thus, it might be said that there was actually no shift in emphasis but simply the emergence of income reporting from either no data at all or rudimentary presentations to the in- come statement as it is known today. This emergence, although starting in the 1920's and early 1930's, was accelerated after the creation of the SEC and was completed by the mid-1990's. The following examples will support these observations. 81 ILLUSTRATION IX List of Annual Reports Reviewed Company 1. Allis-Chalmers Company 2. American Can Company 3. Anaconda Company 4. B. F. Goodrich Company 5. E. I. du Pont 6. F. W. Woolworth Company 7. General Electric Corporation 8. General Motors Corporation 9. International Harvester Company 10. Owens-Illinois 11. P. Lorillard Company 12. Procter & Gamble Company 13. Pullman Incorporated 14. Republic Steel Corporation 15. Sears Roebuck Company 16. Standard Oil Corporation (N.J.) l7. Uniroyal 18. United Fruit Company 19. United States Steel Corporation 20. Westinghouse Electric Reports Reviewed 1912-15; 1915-50 1915-50 1914-50 1914-50 1914-50 1893-1950 1916-50 1917-50 1907-50 1924-50 1919-50 1920-50 1918-50 1906-50 1918-50 1892-1950 1900-50 1912-50 1906-50 1917-50 82 In its third annual report of 1895 General Electric presented a Consolidated Profit and Loss Account as shown in Illustration X, page 83. Yet despite this inclusion, the report highlighted a discussion of the valuation of assets, reassuring the stockholders that all assets were conser- vatively valued. In 1912 the company published a crude Condensed Profit and Loss Account in multiple-step form. Even though this was an advancement, in terms of today's standards of presentation, the report still highlighted balance sheet data. In its 1926 annual report a Comparative Statement of Income and Expenses replaced the old Condensed Profit and Loss Account as shown in Illustration XI, page 89. Yet, little explanatory information was provided for income statement items. It wasn't until its 1930 annual report that the company presented on the first two pages detailed data as to earnings both past and present. By 1991 the emer- gence of income reporting was essentially complete for the General Electric Company. That year's annual report con— tained detailed explanations of each section of the income statement, including appropriate explanations of taxes ex- pense, depreciation, and even dividends. In fact, at the be- ginning of the report there was a special section entitled "Highlights of the Year" containing sales, profits, dividends, and earnings per share data. In its first annual report of 1893 the United States Rubber Company (Uniroyal) included a balance sheet in modern type report format, but included no income statement data nor even sales data. The tenth annual report of 1903 saw the 83 Nashua NNKK NNNK xxxx............mmmH .Hm xumaomh .oocmamm xxxx .....ucooomaa can umoumunH xxxx ..... .....vmcao mwflUHuzo now no mvoovw>wa can amououcH xx muwwoum xxvaom can mofiuamxom xxx“ ....................mqum “know uaouuno onu mo mmocwmam xxxx NMMM flmmm ................mommoa xuvnam xxxx ..........mowu0uco>cH msoauw> xxxx .......mom«nonmum can mucouwm Ammo vowumno 302 munsoa< nonuunm xxxx Nflflfl NMWM ................wdnm>wwumm munnooo< van mouoz so xxxx .................muumuunou can munoecwwmnoo .nuamam no "How coBOHHn nouumwuounoa Hmcowuuvc< xxx mmo nouuaus muumuuaou van mucoacwamaou "mmonwmsm .mumow ucouuso ou hauuom can m=o«>oum cu xauumm oHnmowumnu mommoa xxxx Mfiwfi monogamous no umououcm xxxx MMMM .................mmxm8 can nonconxm Houonmu can Hawog xxxx ..........vHom «@000 no umou nanny uaouuno onu mo nmoawmsm xxxx..¢¢wfl .Hm hunnnxh no no monnanm vounshvx mama .Hm xuwacmn mo unsooo< smog can uwwoum causewaomnou UHmHUmAN Afit as formulated by Adam Smith.“r This transition can be sseeean by comparing Quesnay's views of profits to those of Turgot. Quesnay divided society into three classes: The culti— \7a11:ors (productive class), artisans (the stipendiary class), €1I1rn this statement on the division of the annual produce, 53n15;1:h then considered the money value, called revenue, of 't}1€3 annual produce in Book 11, Chapter II. Here, gross revenue “75153 defined as "the whole annual value of land and labour;" IIEETI :revenue as "what remains free...after deducting the expense ()1? Inuaintaining first...fixed, and secondly,...circulating capi- tal . H 21 \ 33 19Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations (New Rochelle, New €323¥fl<§i Arlington House, Edwin Cannan, editor, reprint of 1776 lstldon), Book I, Chapter V1, p. 52. 20Ibid., Book 11, pp.55-57. 2libid., Book II, pp.309-305. 113 Other classical writers also meant by profits the income obtained from the employment of stock or capital by its em— ployers. For example, Ricardo stated in the preface of his Principles that "the produce of the earth" is divided among f the "three classes of the community, namely, the pr0prietor of the land, the owner of the stock or capital necessary for its cultivation, and the labourers by whose industry it is culti- vated."22 Further, he spoke of "the proportions of the whole produce of the earth which will be allotted to each of these classes, under the names of rent, profit and wages." Malthus, although violently disagreeing with Ricardo as to the causes of fluctuation in profits, described profits as "that portion of the national revenue which goes to the capitalists in return for employment of his capital."2Ur John Stuart Mill referred to profits as "the share of the produce of the capitalists" or 25 the "gains of the persons who advance the expense of production." flimHIary of the Concept of Profit as a Class Income Earlier writers and the classical school generally re— garded profit as a class income. The Physiocrats postulated a C301'1cept of profit in the form of a "surplus" accruing to the agJI‘Z'chultural entrepreneur. The classical school generally \ 22David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and on (New York: E. P. Dutton and Company, Inc., reprint of Taxati the 181 edition, 1937), original preface, p. l. 23 , Ibid., pp. 1—2. (N 2”Thomas R. Malthus, Principles of Political Economy eciTV‘7.York: Augustus M. Kelley, Inc., 1951, reprint of the 1820 lthn), p. 262. Yo 25John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy (New lggk 3 Augustus M. Kelley, Bookseller, reprint of third edition 2 1961), Book II, Chapter XV, p. 905. 3 119 regarded profit as the return for the owner of capital al- though at times it was not clearly distinguished from interest. Influence on Accounting Thought and Practice The importance of the economic concept of profit as a class income to accounting in general and to the shift in interest from the balance sheet to the income statement in particular is indirect and not a result of any overt effort to borrow from economics. But the economic concept of profit as a class income found expression in certain practices or relationships indicated in financial statements and in the development of the proprietary theory of accounting. In fact, there probably was an interaction of the two disciplines, or, one might argue that the influence could even have been from accounting to economics. Chapter II pointed out that the essential form of financial statements was nearly completed at the turn of this century although underlying concepts were still not developed Further, it was also pointed out that accounting before this time was designed to aid the owner-manager in a very limited manner in his business ventures. In fact, early accounting thought and practices were constrained by a tremendously dif— ferent type of economy from that existing today. Practically all business was transacted by a sole proprietor in his own behalf; the separation of management and ownership was almost unthinkable. \ 2 . . 63 .SHendPlkSon contends that the "fields of accounting and C101"lcbmics developed during the nineteenth century and the early EWentieth century independently of each other." Eldon S. enCilrikson, Accounting Theory (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. IPWin, Inc., 1965), p. us. 115 According to Edward Peragallo in a period extending from 1559 to 1795, roughly the era of the Mercantilists and Physiocrats, accounting literature began to break away from nuare description of business practices and include elements of theoretical research even though the double entry method as espoused by Pacioli remained essentially unchanged.27 Thno important developments early in this period parallel the previously mentioned economic views of the mercantilists and physiocrats with respect to their conception of profit. The first important development was the introduction in l608 by Simon Stevin of the use of a "balance account" to :fEicilitate annual profit and loss calculations instead of at the end of each venture. This practice was followed by a proposal in 1673 by a French writer, Jacques Savary, that a balance sheet (”Inventaire") be required by merchants at least every two years so all of their "fixed and movable pro- IDEBITties and their debts receivable and payable" be disclosed.28 frlieaire exist some parallelisms between the mercantilists' and IDTlsrssiocrats' concepts of profit and the above-mentioned develop- DHEEInfts in accounting. Yet it was the introduction of the French 1:}léecory "des cinq comptes generaus" (of the five general accounts) 3111. ‘the latter part of the eighteenth century that really re- SeJubiled their concepts of profit. In addition, the classical E3 27Edward Peragallo, Origin and Evolution of Double Entry OC>kkzee in (New York: American Institute Publishing Company, 1938 , p. 73. 28A. C. Littleton, Accounting Evolution to 1900 (New York: (\nnEIfiican Institute Publishing Company, Inc., 1933), pp. 132—136. 116 concept of profit as the income of those who had the status of an employer of capital and the proprietary theory of accounting also had certain parallelisms. Edmond Degrange was responsible for developing the French theory "des cinq comptes generaus" in his 1795 book "La Tenue des livres rendue facile, ou Nouvelle methode d' enseignement de la tenue des livre en single et double partie"(Bookkeeping made easy, through the Account Method of Teaching both Single and Double Entry). This book attempted to place double entry on a theor- etical footing. He divided accounts into two groups: the first included those of debtors and creditors, and the second, gen- eral accounts of the proprietor which included cash, merchan- dise, negotiable instruments receivable and payable, and profit and loss. The proprietor was the center of the ac- counting process. The essence of the method was debit him Who receives and credit him who gives. Degrange's theory attempted to personalize all accounts and transactions in an attempt to represent the debtor and creditor relationships between merchants and classes in French economic society. This a~‘t‘I:empt resembles certain aspects of the Physiocratic system. Particularly, it is an accounting system that stressed the pro- PI‘ietary class and attempted to represent interrelationships between economic classes. In the early stages of the industrial revolution in Amer— lea the great merchant capitalists--John Hancock, Stephen Girard, Elias Darby, and John Jacob Astor-—emerged. These men operated their empires mostly by a unique system of barter and treated 117 each undertaking as a separate venture. As a result, there was no need to calculate periodic profit and loss.29 As the industrial revolution proceeded, new conditions created a need for new forms of business leadership. To fill this need the industrial capitalists like Andrew Carnegie, Philip Armour, and Gordon McKay appeared. These men applied new technology and mass production techniques while operating their businesses as essentially owners-managers. Economists responded to these new environmental circum- stances by concentrating on a class income concept of profit obtained from the employment of capital by its employers. Accountants likewise responded, although a little later than economists, by developing the proprietary theory of accounting. The German author Scha°r and an American writer Charles E. Sprague were mainly responsible for its development. The latter developed his version in 1880 by contributing a series Of articles to a New York periodical, The Bookkeeper under the title "Algebra of Accounts." The central concept in the proprietary theory is that the prOprietor is placed in the central position of the account- ing equation. Assets represent things owned by the proprietor wh-eI‘eas liabilities were his debts. Nominal accounts represented cnie-I‘lges in the pr0prietorship. The maintenance of the proprietor' s \ 9 . . . . . L - 2 W. T. Baxter, "Accounting in Colonial America" in A. C. lt‘tleton and B. S. Yamey (eds.), Studies in the History of (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956) QQOL'u’itin pP- 28 -281. Je 30Herman E. Kroose, American Economic DeveloPment (New rsey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1962) pp. 272—275. Un‘ 31A. C. Littleton, Essays on Accountancy (Urbana, Illinois: lVersity of Illinois Press, 1961), p. 63. 118 "capital" resulted in a structure based on the accounting equation or balance sheet.32 Thus, in accounting statements and other presentations, profits, as in the economists' theory, were considered a class income of the proprietor. The Concept of Profit as Surplus Remuneration to the Entrepreneur General In 1803 Jean-Baptiste Say was the first to distinguish the concept of an entrepreneur-business manager from the capi— talist—employer and to define his functions. The entrepreneur was made "the principal and active agent of production" and is the distributor of the product to "the productive services in 33 accordance to their function." In short, Say's system in- troduced explicitly the three factors of production by utilizing a concept of the entrepreneur which paved the way for later profit theories and, as we shall see, influenced the development of the entity theory in accounting. Francis A. Walker Francis Walker introduced the concept of the entrepreneur into English economics in 1887.31+ He approached the subject of ’ profit by considering "the share of the produce going to the employer" who "may or may not be the owner," but "constituted a distinct class, either naturally or artifically defined." 32Hendrickson, op. cit., p. 29. 33Charles Gide and Charles Rist, A History of Economic Doctrines (New York: D. C. Heath and Company, second English ealtion, 1999), pp. 128—129. 3L'Francis A. Walker, "The Source of Business Profits," :flye Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. I (April, l887),pp. 265-288. 3SIbid.. p~ 259- 119 Business profits were considered to be the remuneration of this employing class.36 According to Walker business profits for a businessman would be the difference he could make as an em- ployer versus an employee. Thus, he conceived the minimum 37 If an rate of profits to be the current rate of wages. employer makes more than the current rate of wages, it is the result of his superior business ability, and it was measured by the surplus "after payment of wages, the purchase of mater— ial and supplies, and the repair and renewal of machinery and plant."38 F. W. Taussig Professor Taussig of Harvard was another exponent of the concept of profit as surplus remuneration to the entre— preneur. Like Walker, he regarded business as a form of wages.39 His classification of incomes was based upon the return from three factors: land, labor and capital. This classification is implicitly revealed in the following passage: The business man stands at the helm of industry and guides its operations....He pays to the hired workman his stipulated wages. Similarly, to those who lend him money, he pays interest. It is his weighing and guessing of the money—making possibilities of different sites that determine the rent of urban land, and he pays to landowners their rents. After making these payments, he retains in his own hand what is left. His income may, therefore, be described as a residual. 36Ibid., p. 270. 37Ibid., p. 271. 381bid., p. 279. 39F. W. Taussig, Principles of Economics (New York: The Macmillan Company, 19137: Vol. II, p. 158. ”01bid., p. 159. 120 Taussig contended that this position of residual claimant was the reason for the business man's irregularity of income and was caused by his "assumption of industrial hazards" viz. casualty losses, price fluctuations, inven- 91 Over tions and new processes, and fluctuation in demand. a period of years, Taussig then argued that the effects of these hazards balanced out, and the critical variables thus causing differences in the long-run earnings of different business men are the possession of the qualities shrewdness, ability, and skin.”2 J. A. Hobson Hobson divided factorial incomes of rent, wages, and interest each into three parts. Each part represented a sort of "charge" to total income from the productive process. The first charge was for costs, "that part of the product necessary to maintain the current output of productive energy in a factor of production." That portion of the product which remained after these costs were defrayed he called surplus. This surplus was then divided into produc- tive and unproductive portions. The former represented the second charge and consisted of payments to owners of the factors of production in excess of cost as are necessary to evoke an increase of industrial structure or power(i. e. growth in the supply of these factors). The latter, ”llbid., pp. 159-160. ”ZIbid., p. 161. 121 unproductive surplus, consisted of the remaining part of the surplus that must be paid to the owners of the factors of production as are 393 necessary to secure an increase of in- dustrial structure or power. The question that is relevant is: Where does the Surplus originate? It comes from the other factor of production, "ability," that is, the ability of the entrepreneur to organize and direct production. Hobson believed that the payment of this ability factor, excluding interest and payment for risk, but including what was commonly termed "wages of management or superintendence," was profit.uu In short, he thought profit to be the necessay supply—price to stimulate the activity of the entrepreneur. Its theoretical maximum consisted of the "difference between the sum of the productivity of the separate unorganized units of the factors of production and the sum of their productivity when organized," whereas, its theoretical minimum simply represented the above-mentioned first charge to total income.”5 The actual profit was between these upper and lower limits and depended upon: (1) bargaining power of the entrepreneur over the other factors, and (2) the competitive situation for the firm's products.Ll6 Thus, it must be concluded that Hobson also regarded profit as the remuneration of the entrepreneur and dependent upon his ability even though like n I+3J.A. Hobson, The Industrial System, an Inquiry into 'Qgpned and Unearned Income (London, England: P. S. King and Son, Ltd., revised edition, 1910), pp. 56-82. ””Ibid., p. 122. usIbid., p. 129. L*5Ibid., p. 129-125. 122 every other income the surplus obtained over the minimum supply-price is a function of various competitive conditions in the bargaining process.”7 Herbert J. Davenport Another economist who represented the concept of profit as surplus entrepreneurial remuneration is Professor Davenport. Like the previous writers he stated that "compensation for the entrepreneur is profit,"“’8 where "all employers of labor or of instrumental goods for hire are entrepreneurs, no matter whether the prospective product is to be offered for sale or not.“49 He presented three alternative explanations for profit: (1) "ex- ceptional, unclassified, irregular gains--conjunctive profits..., (2) compensation for the independently working human factor in production..., and (3) compensation for the independent human "50 Davenport preferred the third factor in the quest for gain. sense because it denoted "compensation falling to independent business activity after such apportionment as is possible has been made for rent, interest, wages, and other outlays." Fur- ther, in this sense "profit stands as merely one form of remun- eration of labor" and is thus a form of wages to the entrepreneur for entrepreneurial activity as such.51 From this notion of profit Professor Davenport then stated ‘that this profit goes "to him who takes the risk." Furthermore, ”7Haney, 0p. cit., p. 871. |+8Herbert Joseph Davenport, The Economics of Enterprise (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1913), p. 67. IL'gihid., p. 139. 50Ibid., p. 909. 51Ibid. 123 he stated that it is in the very "nature of entrepreneur labor that it is the labor of the risk—taker."52 This View, as will be discussed later, anticipated Knight's concept of profit, viz. profit as a return to uncertainty bearing. John Bates Clark J. B. Clark, an American economist, developed a dynamic theory of the entrepreneur which was to have an important in— fluence on the development of profit theories in economics and accounting. As has been shown, early writers and the classical school generally conceived the entrepreneur to be the capitalist- employer. It was further shown that Walker differentiated the capitalists from the employer, who may or not be the same. Clark went one more step and confined the entrepreneur to a solely coordinating role. For example he states: This purely coordinating work we shall call the entrepreneur's function, and the rewards for it we shall call profits. The function in itself includes no working and no owning of capital: it consists entirely in the establishing and main- taining of efficient relations between the agents of production. In short, the entrepreneur became "the man who coordinates capi— tal and labour, without in his own prOper capacity furnishing either of them."5u Thus, he postulated that the three functions of the capitalists,the manager, and the owner, although fre- quently combined as one and the same person, were theoretically distinct. ‘ 5216id. 53John Bates Clark, The Distribution of Wealth (New York: films Macmillan Company, 1899), pp. 2-3. 5”John Bates Clark, "Insurance and Business Profits," IESinuarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. II (October, 1892), p.96. 129 According to Clark the rewards of these three functions were also distinct because the growth of corporations had tended to separate these functions into bondholders and credi- tors, salaried officials representing owners, and stockholders respectively.55 Pure profit in the proprietorship form of business was the return of simple ownership. However, in the large corporation with many stockholders "pure profit resides in the portion of dividends that is in excess of current inter— . . . 56 est on the paid in capital." Clark's measure of profit was similar to the cash method used by today's accountants. For example, he stated: Defray all the expenses of bringing a pro- duct into existence, sell the article for what you can get, and, if you have anything more in your hands than you had at the beginning of the operation, you have received a true profit.... an excess of an entrepreneur's receipts over all his disbursements. Although Clark felt that "risk—taking" is necessary, it was not considered a part of pure profit, as will be shown in Knight's theory. Capitalists were considered the risk-takers. Their return is interest. Profit "begins only when something comes to the entrepreneur over and above this and all other disbursements.58 Eyederick Barnard Hawley The "risk theory of profits" proposed by Hawley was a theory «1150 based on a concept of pure profit as a residual surplus 55Ibid., pp. us—u9. 56John Bates Clark, "Profits Under Modern Conditions," Eglitical Science Quarterly,Vol. II, p. 607. 57Clark, "Insurance and Business Profits," op. cit.,p. 91. Ibid. 125 return to the entrepreneur. His theory is summarized in his own words as follows: The final consumer is forced to include in the price he pays for any product not only enough to cover all items of cost to the entrepreneur,—— among which items is a sum sufficient to cover the actuarial or average loss incidental to the risks of all kinds necessarily assumed by the entrepreneur and his insurers,--but a further sum, without which, as an inducement, the entrepreneur, or enterpriser, and his insurers will not undergo or suffer the irksomeness of being exposed to risk. This surplus of consumer's cost over entre- preneur's cost, universally regarded as profit, and, from the nature of the case, an unpredetermined residue, is the inducement for the assumption by the entrepreneur, or enterpriser, of all risks, whatever their nature, necessitated by the process of pro— duction. As an inducement to any given action and the reward for the action are the same thing,—-the difference being not in the thing itself, but only in the point of time from which it is looked upon,-- the unpredetermined residue which served as the inducement to risk at the commencement of any indus- trial transaction must necessarily, when determined and realized at its close, be regarded as the result, or reward, of the risks undergone.59 It appears that Hawley's concept of pure profit only differed from that of Clark's in their respective concept of the entrepreneur and the capitalists and his emphasis on risk. As was stated earlier Clark maintained that the capitalist is the risk-taker and his reward is interest which included rent. The entrepreneur he explained: becomes the owner of the product of this industry, as they are turned out, and sells them in the mar— ket for what he can get. In acquiring this owner— ship, he must pay all costs entailed in creating the product; and among the cost to be thus defrayed is the entire sum paid over to the capitalists as an offset of risk. 0 59Frederick B. Hawley, "Reply to Final Objections to the Risk Theory of Profits," Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol. XV, (August, 1901), p. 610. 60Clark, "Insurance and Business Profits," op.cit.,p. 96 126 Thus, Hawley believed that profit was "the result of risks wisely selected."61 He made pure profit a specific reward for the service of risk-taking. Enterprise was considered the fourth. factor of production. Profit was a cost in the supply price of the product. Profit was the cause of rent, interest, and wages. Enterprise was considered the servant of society, whereas the other three factors were the servants of enterprise.62 Alfred Marshall Marshall's approach to a theory of profit, although basic— ally a surplus—reward—of—the-entrepreneur was rather eclectic. For Marshall, business profits Were the total net gains from a- 63 business which motivated a man in his business. This usually implies a composite of many items as is shown in a quotation from Schumpeter: But in it (Marshall concept of profit) the ordinary reader finds a fricasee of such things as: earnings of management of all possible kinds, including also the earnings of better than com- mon management; gains from successful risk-taking and uncertainly bearing...; gains from advantage ‘incident to the control of particular factors, some of which would, in other firms, not contri- bute as much to results as they do where they are; chance gains to the owner as residual clai- ment...; and, among other things, gains which accrue to a firm as it grows, or because it has grown, rglative to its competitors or absolutely or both. H 6lFrederick Barnard Hawley, Enterprise and the Productive Process (New York and London: G. P. Putnam's Sons, The Knicker- bocker Press, 1907), p. 108. 621bid., p. 96. 63Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics (London: Mac- millan and Company, Ltd., eighth edition, 1920, first edition, 1890), p. 73. 6“'Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of EconomicsAnalysis (Ahew York: Oxford University Press, 1959), p. 1099. 127 Certainly this concept of profit is quite different from those concepts which explain profits as a result of only one factor. The wide range of possibilities as Marshall referred indicates the difficulties he thought were in this area of theory. Irving Fisher Schumpeter contends that Irving Fisher was America's "greatest scientific economist."65 He was interested in measu— ring income and profit as surplus remuneration to the entrepreneur as is demonstrated in his famous book The Nature of Capital and Shicome when he writes: This book is an attempt to put on a rational foundation the concepts and fundamental theorems of capital and income. It, therefore, forms a sort of philosophy of economic accounting, and, it is hoped may supply a link long missing between ideas and usages underlying practical business transactions and the theories of abstract economics.66 In formulating his theory of income and profit, which was bafiBically a surplus reward of the entrepreneur, Fisher differ- erltiilated between a stock and a flow of wealth. A stock of wealth 313 ainy given point of time he calls "capital;" the flow of ser— "67 Vchzeas from this stock during a period of time is "income. PiEsl'ieruses the term wealth to identify "material objects owned Having seen what bS’ finndividuals" and that provide a service. EELESIIGEr defined wealth to be, it is necessary to examine its first e S s e ntial attribute-materiality . \ 65Joseph A. Schumpeter, Ten Great Economists from Marx to iS§Z§1335§£§ (New York: Oxford University Press, 1965), p. 223. 66Irving Fisher, The Nature of Capital and Income (New York Pi - -. 51(21Ttlfillan Company, 1906), p. Vii. 67Ibid., p. 51. 68Ibid., p. 3. 128 Materiality of wealth is important because it provided the basis for a physical measurement of the various articles of wealth. Fisher pointed out that even though each item of wealth has a unit of measurement (i. e. pounds, feet, gallons), it is convenient to measure the combined value of aggregations of wealth in terms of money. The term value is important for this measurement process and was made to depend upon price; that of price, in turn, on that of exchange; and finally, that of exchange on that of transfer. Starting with transfer Fisher then discusses the sequence which later enters into the account- ant's debits and credits.69 Like the first attribute of wealth, materiality, the secnond ownership, must be reviewed in order to clearly under— stan d Fisher's theory . Fisher contended that to own wealth is to have a "right tC) ijhe benefits of wealth."70 For example, to own a loaf of brxeaid meant to have the right to satisfy one's desires (i.e. eéit: .it, sell it, and etc.). The flow of benefits from wealth, 111 ifhe most general sense, is what is meant by income, accord- illég to Fisher.71 It is a utility concept of income. Opposed to the benefits or services derived from wealth alpei costs. Fisher called these costs "negative benefits or diSServices." The purpose of wealth, as previously mentioned, Was to furnish the owner satisfaction from its use. This satis- faction may be an event he did not wish to happen. Sometimes, \ Yko 69Irving Fisher, Elementary Principles of Economics (New >1?}<-= The Macmillan Company, 1911), pp. 10—15. 7OFisher, op. cit., The Nature of Capital and Income, p.18. 7llbid., p. 101. 129 however, wealth can provide no benefit without entailing some cost (1. e. preventing what is desirable or causing what is undesirable). For example, one must maintain a house (repairs, enjoy its use; a businessman must 72 taxes and etc.) in order to pay a worker to obtain the benefits of his services. Starting with these concepts of services and disservices, Fisher then formulated the necessary requirements for the com— pletion of every economic event. There must be an "acting" instrument or set of instruments, and there must be an instru- ment or set of instruments acted upon, which he labeled "active" and."passive," respectively. For example, the equipment of a ttxol manufacturer and his employees' labor are active in making a liammer, whereas, the materials contained in the hammer are Luasssive. Later, the hammer in the hands of a carpenter building a 11c>use is active; the lumber used in the constructing, passive. TC> 1:hese double—faced events Fisher gave the name "interactions"-- It . . . . . . a. 53erv1ce of the acting instrument and a disseerce of the in- Ertletiment acted upon."73 Interactions were the key because income for any group of capital consisted of the interactions taking place within that g17<>11p. But it is the outer fringe of services that constitute t17L1€3 income of that group. To Fisher, this final income was -pfs§7<211ic income, of which money income was an approximation. It was shown that Fisher viewed the term "capital" as not -tc> IDEE confined to any particular kind of wealth, but it applies \ 72Fisher, 0p. cit., Elementary Principles, pp. 21-23. 3 . Fisher, op2 cit., The Nature of Capital and Income,p. 199. 130 to all kinds existing at an instant of time. In addition, it was shown that Fisher regarded income as consisting simply of the benefits of wealth. Finally, Fisher believed both can be subjected to money measures, even though approximated at times. In spite of this close association, capital and income have been essentially considered separately. The question now is: how did Fisher pass from capital to income and income to capital? This bridge or link was the rate of interest, which necessarily involves the discounting of expected future income. To use Fisher terminology: "the rate of interest is the premium vdiich present goods command over similargoods of the future."7u IT: short, Fisher used the rate of interest as the appropriate ditscount factor to translate future money-values into current Hubruey-values. The rate of interest is thus a link between \Nalnies at two points of time. Or more specifically, the value CDf' cany item of capital is the discounted value of income expected 3frk3rn.that capital. As Fisher states: The present worth of anything is what men are willing to give for it. In order that each man may decide what he is willing to give, he must have: (1) some idea of the future benefits his purchase will bring him, and (2) some idea of the rate of interest by which these future values may be translated into present values by discounting."75 With the above discussion of Fisher's concept of income <3C>nfl£>leted, it now seems appropriate to consider the impact of -t}1€3 <2oncept of profit as a surplus return to the entrepreneur on ‘t}1€3 sshift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income state— mEI'lt . \ 7L'Fisher, 0p. cit., Elementary Principles, pp. 96—97. 7SIbid., p. 99. 131 Summary‘of'the.Conceptfiof'ProfitrasVSurplus Remuneration to the Entrepreneur The importance of this concept of profit to economics was the fact that profit was no longer identified with any particular class but was a sort of opportunity payment or re— ward for managerial skill. The entrepreneur or organizer of the productive process was made the central "cause" of profit. His function was theoretically distinguished from the capitalist- owner reflecting the increased importance of the corporation with its corresponding separation of stockholders and managers. Profit was measured by economists espousing this concept by the surplus or residual amount remaining after making necessary factor payments for land, labor, and capital. Some of the writers felt that profits were the result of superior managerial ability. Others believed it resulted from the assumption of risk. But all believed that interest was a return to the factor capital and must clearly be separated from profit. Relationship of the Economist's Concept of Profit as Surplus Entrepreneurial Remuneration to Accounting General The latter part of the nineteenth and early part of the twentieth centuries saw the downfall of the industrial capitalist and the emergence of the corporate form of business organization. Gardiner C. Means suggested that: This development, culminating in the separa- tion of ownership and control has brought a change in the character of industry as revolutionary as that produced by the industrial revolution with its corres— ponding division of function, the separation of labor and control.76 ‘ 75Gardiner C. Means The Cor orate Revolutio ' ° ”Jew York: The Crowell-Collier PuBIisHing Company, 1962), p.CI5. 132 As was mentioned before, economists responded to this changing economic scene by developing a concept of profit based upon surplus entrepreneurial remuneration. Accountants also respon- ded to the changing environment by reviving the entity theory and introducing the going concern concept, thus, calling for a periodic annual report of management's accomplishments, which in turn, led to matching revenue realized against cost consumed through the tool of the income statement as a practical solution to the calculation of income. The entity theory stresses the separateness of the "busi- ness" and the proprietor like the economist's entrepreneurial theory. The fundamental accounting equation becomes Assets: Equities. Littleton points out that with the entity theory new emphasis is directed at distinguishing between capital and in- come, a necessary condition for an accurate measurement of income as Irving Fisher apprOpriately pointed out. For example Littleton stated in discussing the difference between the pro- prietary and entity theories: ...so fundamental a difference in point of View as this must be indicative of an underlying difference in the concepts of the real function of bookkeeping and of capital and income. Capital, according to the proprietorship view, is the pro- prietor's contribution; liabilities are merely nega- tive assets. But in the entity theory, capital is the sum total of property active in the business from Whatever source derived;...Protit, according to the proprietary theory, is an increase in the net figure of positive and negative property (i.e. net assets); in the equity theory, profit is the excess of the proceeds recovered over the out— lays advanced during the business process. In the first view, profit is any increment to proprietor— ship however obtained; in the other, it is the reward for managerial skill in advancing such outlays as will produce an excess when recovered.77 77Littleton,’0p.' cit., Accounting Evolution to 1900, p. 192. 133 From this quotation two important ideas remind one of the economist's concept of profit as surplus remuneration of the entrepreneur. Particularly, profit as "the excess of the proceeds recovered over the outlays advanced" is very similar to how the above—mentioned economists viewed profit (viz. "sur— plus after payment of wages, the purchase of materials and supplies, and the repair and renewal of machinery and plant.")78 Secondly, profit as the "reward for managerial skill in ad- vancing such outlays as will produce an excess when recovered" is exactly the same notion utilized by most proponents of the surplus entrepreneurial reward concept of profit. William Andrew Paton Although development of the entity theory during the latter part of the nineteenth century occurred in Germany, it was Paton who was primarily responsible for its introduction and expansion in the United States. In his 1922 edition of Accounting Theory, he clearly recognized "the relations between certain accounting concepts and fundamental classes of economic theory. For example, in discussing one of his fundamental classes "properties" he wrote: A consideration of the relation of the class, "properties," to the economist's concept, "wealth," will serve to throw some light upon the fundamental nature of this accounting category. In general it may be said that anything which can conStitute wealth may, under certain circumstances, become an asset to the accountant.80 78See footnote 38, 90, and 93. 79William Andrew Paton, AccOunting Theory(Chicago, Illinois: Accounting Studies Press, Ltd., 1962, reprint of the 1922 edition), P- v. ' 801bid., p. 33. 139 Furthermore he stated: "Evidently the accountant's class, prOperties, is somewhat akin to the economist's capital."81 The most significant relation between economics and accounting for the purposes of this study was his adoption of the entity theory. In the preface of Accounting Theory he wrote: In this book,...., an attempt has been made to present a restatement of the theory of accounting consistent with the conditions and needs of the business enterprise "par excellence," the large corporation, as well as applicable to the simpler, more primitive forms of organization. The conception of the business enterprise as in all cases a distinct entity or personality--an extension of the 82 fiction of the corporate entity--is adopted,.... Further, in his chapter on the postulates of accounting Paton stated: The concept of the business entity is con— stantly used outside the corporate form of or- ganization by economists and others interested in the business process.83 Along with the entity theory the concept of "going con- cern" was also listed as a corollary postulate. Littleton con- tends that the "relationship between regular periodic reporting and the concept of enterprise continuity is clearly evident." Particularly, he believes that "periodic reports were the con— "89 sequence of the acceptance of the idea of enterprise continuity With the acceptance of the entity theory and periodic reporting n 8libid., p. 35. 821bid., p. v. 83Ibid., p. 979. 8"FA. C. Littleton and V. K. Zimmerman, Aeoounting Theory: Egfljjnuity and Change (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice- Hall, Inc., 1962), pp. 55-56. 135 the ground work in theory was complete for the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement and the development of the transactions approach to income account— ing. To use Emily Chen Chang's words: The income statement is elevated as the most significant financial statement, an exhibi— tion of management accomplishments and a measure- ment of the corporation's earning power; while the balance sheet is belittled as a means of carrying forward unamortized acquisition prices, an exhibition of unfinished jobs. The business entity is the center of attention, and the in- terests of individual stockholders are pushed into the background. The Concept of Profit as a Return to Uncertainty Bearing General In an earlier section of this chapter the interaction of ideas and events between accounting and economics in response to environmental forces was presented. For example, the introduction of the so-called "balance account" by Simon Stevin, the "Inventaire" by Jacques Savary, and Edmond Degrange's theory "des cinq comptes generoux" re- sembled certain of the ideas found in the mercantilists' and physiocrats' writings. Furthermore, it was shown that there was an interaction between the classical economist's concept of profit as a result of the employment of capital and the develop- ment of the proprietary theory in accounting. In the next section the economist's concept of profit as a surplus remuneration to the entrepreneur, in responding to the corporate revolution was related to the revival and expansion ‘ 85Emily Chen Chang, "Business Income In Accounting and Economics" * Accounting Review, Vol. XXXVII (October 1962), p.638. 136 of the entity theory in accounting. It was then argued that the entity theory and the corresponding going concern concept led to periodic reporting of management's accomplishments. The outcome was the transactions approach to income accounting and a belittling of the balance sheet. As an appropriate sequel it seems desirable to briefly demonstrate, as further proof of interactions of ideas and events in economics and accounting, the relationship of the economist's concept of profit as a return for uncertainty bearing to current accounting thought. Frank Knight Frank Knight developed a theory of profit which showed that the presence of uncertainty about the future may allow entrepreneurs to earn positive profits despite product ex— haustion and competitive equilibrium.86 Unlike J. B. Clark and F. B. Hawley, profit appeared only when there is an accretion to the present value of the expected future net receipts of a firm's capital. In addition, he criticized both the dynamic theory of Clark and the risk theory of Hawley as applied to the entrepreneur. Concerning the former Knight wrote: "it is not dynamic change, nor any change as such, which causes profit."87 The latter, Hawley, was criticized because "he treats risk as a known quantity and concentrated on entrepreneurial 'ability'."88 86M. Blaug, 0p. cit., p. 939. 87Frank H. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit (New York: Kelley and Millman, Inc., 1952, reprint of the 1921 edition),p.38. 88Ibid., p. 95. 137 Professor Knight formulated his analysis of the cause of profit on what he called "unmeasurable uncertainty." He believed that individuals do not act upon inferences of logical reasoning, based upon exact knowledge of things. Instead indiv— iduals act upon estimates, opinions, judgment, or intuition based upon imperfect knowledge of the data and their environment.89 Estimates were considered somewhat like a particular type of probability judgment. He regarded this type as true "uncertainty" and "liable to err" because these estimates were incapable of being based upon any classification of instances. This inability of classifying instances was the important fact that differentiated estimates from’é priori judgments and sta- tistical probability judgments. These latter types of judgments were measurable more or less and were called "risks."90 It is this unmeasurable uncertainty that was the cause of profit and loss. Furthermore, unmeasurable uncertainty forced the entrepreneur to exercise "responsible control" and to bear its burden. This control and uncertainty-bearing, unlike Hawley's formulation, was inseparable and was the chief function of the entrepreneur.91 According to Knight profit was caused by the margin of error in calculation on the part of the non-entrepreneurs who did not force successful entrepreneurs to pay as much for the factors of production as they could have been forced to pay. In short, profit was the difference between "extante" and "expost" calculations. 89Ibid., pp.223—233. 90Ibid., pp.223-233. 911bid., p. 278. 92Ibid., p. 289. 138 J. R. Hicks Professor J. R. Hicks defined what may be considered the dominant current economic concept of income for an individual as "the maximum value which can be consumed by an individual during a week and still expect to be as well off at the end of "93 the week as he was at the beginning. In short, "the pur— pose of income calculations is to give people some idea as to the amount they can consume without impoverishing themselves."9u This immeasurableness was the case since prices change both relatively and absolutely in addition to the change in the quality of goods produced with the passage of time. Thus, the amount of money that an individual can spend during a given period and still expect to be as well off at the end of the year as he was at the start involves both utility measurement and index number problems.95 If, on the other hand one could Specify a utility function, a solution would be to hold utility constant for the period and measure one's total expenditures during the period. The amount of these total expenditures would be income for the period. If, however, prices change then consumption does not represent income because the same "basket" of goods that keeps utility constant also changes. But Hicks does think that, if certain assumptions are made and price indices are available, one's "ex-poste" income could be calculated. A quotation from Hicks makes this point clear: 93J. R. Hicks, Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic TheOry (Oxford: The Clarendon Press, second edition, 1950), p. 172. 9L'Ibid. 95 Ibid., pp. 179-176. 139 If capital values of an individual's pro- perty can be ascertained at the beginning and ending of a period and if we assume we can measure consumption then one's ex—poste income can be calculated.96 From the definition of an individual's income Hicks then defined business income as the "maximum amount which the firm can distribute as dividends and still expect to be as well off at the end of the period as it was at the beginning." He furthergoes on to state that being well off meant "main- taining capital intact in terms of discounted value of expected "97 Here as with Knight, it seems evident future net receipts. that the future expected net receipts of the factors of pro- duction purchased by a business entity were unknown and sub— ject to risk and uncertainty. It also seems evident that Hicks was implying the capital maintenance approach to periodic in- come measurement. Particularly, the calculation of income involves the capitalization (present discounted value) of the net cash flow to be received by the business at the beginning and ending of the period. Interaction with Current Accounting Thought and Practice Familiarity with current accounting thought and practice makes one realize the growing importance of the concept of cap— italization and uncertainty. This growing importance interacts with the concept of profit as the return to uncertainty bearing with its emphasis on the capital maintenance approach to income measurement and can be said to exist in two significant trends. 96Ibid. 97Ibid., pp. 179-180. 190 The first significant trend is the attempt to make the balance sheet a better tool for valuation and income determina- tion. One of the leading proponents of this View is Professor Chambers. For example, he states: It is contended,..., that the swing from the balance sheet viewpoint to the profit and loss viewpoint has gone too far. It has gone so far, it is believed, because of the desire to bolster conventional accounting methods. In changing conditions the conventional profit and loss account gives a better approximation to current net profit than the conventional balance sheet gives to current financial position. If one claims that the profit and loss account is the most important statement, one can make light of the defects of the conventional balance sheet.... It does not follow from the statement "earning power is the significant basis of enter- prise value" that "the income statement is the most significant accounting report." The income statement does not show earning power; it shows earnings. Earning power is only ascertainable from a comparison of earnings with the sum employed; net profit of itself is not significant. It fol- lows that the income account and the balance sheet are of equal importance for this purpose, and that the further the asset values move from invested cost without restatement of those values and of the shareholder's equity, the greater is the distortion of the current relationship between net profit and the sum employed. In his recent book, Accounting, Evaluation and Economic Behavior, a case is made for the reinstatement of the balance sheet as the primary accounting report. Here, Chambers com- pares business entities to individuals as "homeostatic systems" being influenced by a host of factors, one of which is economic phenomena. The condition which has the greatest influence on the choices of an actor, as he describes it, is his "present position in relation to his environment at any point of time." 98Raymond J. Chambers, "The Implications of Asset Revalu- ation and Bonus Share Issues," Australian Accountant, Vol. 27 (November, 1957), pp. 519-515. 191 In fact, this position "is the determinant and predictor of future positions, as it is also the resultant of past positions." Knowing this position is a necessary, but not a sufficient, 99 To business condition for successful choosing or acting. entities it is financial position as reflected in the balance sheet that serves as the basis for successful choosing or acting. The income statement "is derived, fundamentally, by reference from two successive statements of financial position."100 As a result, the income statement is reduced in importance while the balance sheet is elevated in importance. That is to say, the capital maintenance approach to income determination is adopted. Chambers is decisively different than economists with respect to his valuation concept used for income calculations. He generally adopts what is called the "current cash equivalent" basis for valuation as Opposed to capitalized values based upon expectations. For example he states: Calculations about future conditions and events are always and inevitably hypothetical. No proposition relating to the future is a state- ment of fact. One may use past experience and present knowledge of facts and relationships in forming propositions about the future. But those . . . f . l 101 propOSItions are belie s or expectations on y. It seems that future expectations are most relevant. Current prices under pure competition reflect the interaction of supply and demand forces. One of the most important forces that in- fluence these prices are expectations. Thus, current prices are 9 . . Raymond J. Chambers, Accounting,Evaluation and Economic Behavior (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc.,1966), PP- - 0 Ibid., p. 118. 101Ibid., p. 83. 192 significant, as Chambers suggests, under perfect markets because they reflect expectations not just because they are objective. In imperfect markets current prices are signifi- cant only because they represent the lowest minimum subjective value to an actor comtemplating a purchase. For example, a businessman would not be willing to purchase a machine if its discounted value to him is less than its market price. In short, the principle of capitalization based upon expectations is essential to the whole problem of valuation, which in turn is the basis for action. Thus, valuation is subjective. Re— sulting income calculations are tentative and uncertain. To the extent the current cash equivalents approximate capitalized values then they are relevant to accounting because they meet the other standards of verifiability, freedom from bias, and quantifiability as recently proposed by the American Accounting Association. But to argue that current cash equivalents and resulting current position are the theoretically correct basis for action is incorrect. The second significant trend is the movement toward re— vising the meaning of the realization concept in an effort to provide better income data and to upgrade the status of the balance sheet. Traditionally the time of sale has been the general rule for the recognition or realization of revenue, be- cause it is argued that (l) the price of the product is now established, (2) an exchange or new asset has been acquired, (3) the sale in most instances is deemed to be the most signifi— cant event to a firm, and (9) most of the costs relating to the product have been incurred and are readily determinable.102 102Hendrickson,‘ op. cit., p. 138. 193 In short, the general view is that realization is the recog- nition of revenue when an exchange or severance has occurred. The effect of this strict adherence to the realization concept is that traditional accounting income does not recog- nize (1) changes in net assets not realized in the period (i.e. value added approach), (2) changes in price levels, (3) unexpected changes in expectations, and (9) expected 103 With the possible exception of (3) changes in goodwill. economists take into consideration all these factors in cal- culating income. Today the traditional realization concept is under attack as evidenced by the volumes of literature. Sprouse and Moonitz reject the concept because it is in conflict with the postulate 10” Instead they advocate that recognition should of continuity. be granted in the period in which the major economic activity occurred, providing objective measurements of this activity is available.105 They also believe adjustments for price level changes should be recognized in the period of occurrence. The American Accounting Association has likewise broadened the meaning of realization to include "a change in an asset or liability" if it is "sufficiently definite and objective to warrant recognition in the accounts." Thus realization can re- sult from "an exchange transaction between independent parties, or in established trade practices, or on the terms of a contract 103Chang, op. cit., p. 691. 10L'Robert S. Sprouse and Maurice Moonitz, "A Tentative Set of Broad Accounting Principles for Business Enterprises," Accounting Research Study No. 3 (New York: American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 1962), p. 15. 105 Ibid., p. 97. 199 performance which is considered virtually certain."106 Floyd W. Windal believes that this American Accounting Association definition of realization is broadly stated and seemed to be equally applicable to expenses, gains and losses and other changes in assets and liabilities. For example, he stated that "the key point is whether a change in an asset or liability, presumably any change, has become sufficiently definite and objective to warrant recognition in the accounts."107 He considered an item objective if it appeared "substantially the same to all accountants examining it." By definiteness an item "must appear unlikely to be reversed."108 Further- more, in his concluding remarks Windal suggested that the criteria for realization may change with time. In fact, com- puters, economic structures, and economic stability "may make it possible to forcast with great certainty what lies ahead for an enterprise."109 From the above statements relative to the realization concept, there is evidence that accountants are relaxing the strict requirements of the traditional view. The result is that many contend income accounting should recognize (1) changes in net assets not "realized" in the period if objective veri- fiable evidence exists, and (2) gains and losses from price movements, both general and relative. Thus, the difference between economic income and accounting income is narrowed to 106American Accounting Association Committee on Accounting Concepts and Standards, ACCOuntingand Reporting Standards for Corporate Financial Statements and Preceding Statements and Supplements (Columbus, Ohio: American Accouniing Association, 1957), p. 3. 107Floyd W. Windal, "The Accounting Concept of Realization," ’Accounting Review, Vol. XXXVI (April, 1961), p. 250. lOBIbid., p. 252. 1091513., p. 208. 195 (1) changes in expectations and (2) expected changes in goodwill. If computers, economic structures, economic sta- bility, and fiscal policy continue to reduce uncertainty, then it might be possible to use probability values in ac- counting calculations, thus narrowing the area of disagree— Inent even more. Furthermore, it is felt that concentration on valuation and measurement theory can also reduce the dif— ference. The problem should not be the balance sheet versus the income statement approach to income calculations because valuation of assets and liabilities in the former is merely shifted to the valuation of assets and liabilities entering amid leaving the firm in the latter. Both approaches yield identical results under appropriate valuation methods and :identical assumptions. CHAPTER VI THE INFLUENCE OF FEDERAL TAXATION 8 LEGISLATION General The advent of income taxation and other Federal legis- lation was a factor of marked consequence in the promotion of the income statement viewPoint. Many feel that it is not an exaggeration to say that this development has had more influence than any other factor in bringing about the ascen- dancy of income accounting based upon systematic accounting methods. H. C. Daines suggested this in the following passage: The income tax objective is reflected in the attitude on the part of certain business- men and accountants that the books of accounts should be kept so as to properly record the taxa— ble income. It can be said that many believe that this point of view constitutes the primary purpose of accounting. Federal income taxation, beginning with the 1899 and 1909 acts, was firmly established with the adoption of the Sixteenth Amendment early in 1913. The passage of the first act under this Amendment in 1913 and subsequent legislation imposing even higher rates based upon income and net earnings naturally led businessmen to consider it imperative that profit figures be calculated with the greatest possible degree of precision to 1H. C. Daines, "The Changing Objectives of Accounting", The Accountipg Review, Vol. IV (June, 1929), p. 103. 196 197 insure that minimum legal amounts of taxes were paid. The task of computing this periodic business income was naturally the domain of the accountant. As a result, accountants began to focus increased attention upon the problems associated with the matching of costs and revenues (i. e. timing, recognition, allocation, etc.). The end product of this increased attention was the tendency to present more detailed income statements, in terms of form and content. In fact, in many cases the emer- gence of income reporting for external purposes appeared in smaller companies for the first time simply because the neces- sary information was prepared for tax purposes.2 On the other hand, to suggest that the emergence of income reporting for external parties was solely the result of income taxation is, of course, untrue. The important point, however, is that the tax laws forced businessmen, if they wanted to minimize taxes, to keep appropriate records as to revenue and expense. The other condition that resulted in the emergence of income re- porting was, as mentioned before, the demands and legislation resulting from the increased importance of the small investor. Both the developments in income taxation and the requirements of various governmental legislation as they relate to the external shift from the balance sheet to the income statement are the subject matter of this chapter. 2Paton, William A., Accountipg (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1926) pp. 1—2. 198 Federal Income Taxation The Problem of Income The taxation of income reflects the long term shift from property to income as a measure of economic well being (wealth) or power. The Sixteenth Amendment to the Constitution stated in Article XVI: The Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever source derived, with apportionment among the several states, and without regard to any census or enumeration. One of the first problems encountered as a result of this statement was interpretation of the term income. Much con- fusion resulted because of the various meanings that were available. Economists, as is evidenced by the previous chap- ter, proposed definitions that ranged from the extremely sub— jective or psychic concepts to the more practical or real in- come concepts. Accountants proposed definitions that, in the broadest sense, approached the economic concept of real income to the narrow money income concept, which reflects only realized increases in the monetary valuation of resources. The courts provided definitions that concentrated on the idea of a "gain" as being regarded as income. For example, the U. S. Supreme Court in the famous Eisner V. Macomber case clarified its posi- tion from previous decisions (Stratton's Independence V. Hou- bert, 231 U. S. 339, 915 and Doyle V. Mitchell Brothers Com— pany, 297 U. S. 179, 195): 199 Income may be defined as the gain derived from capital, from labor, or from both combined, provided it be understood to include profit _gained through a sale or conversion of capital assets,...3 This decision crystalized the past vague interpretations of the courts and gave the business community a framework for developing accounting concepts of income that would be accept- able for tax purposes, even though the Revenue Act of 1918 had recognized that "net income of a taxpayer computed in accor— dance with the method of accounting regularly employed" was an acceptable basis for taxable income. Accrual Accounting Although not specifically required, Federal income taxa- tion encouraged accountants and businessmen to use the accrual basis of income determination. This encouragement made it neces- sary for those businesses that adOpted the accrual basis to match revenues with appropriate expenses in ascertaining taxable income.Ll As early as 1918 the tax regulations allowed taxpayers to use accrual accounting for income determination: Gains, profits, and income are to be in- cluded in gross income for the taxable year in which they are received..., unless they are included when they accrue...in accordance with the approved method of accounting followed by the taxpayer. This emphasis on accrual accounting was subsequently repeated 3Eisner V. Macomber, United States Supreme Court, 252, a decision of March 8, 1920, p. 183. UrGeorge 0. May, "Taxable Income and Accounting Bases for Determining It", Journal of Accountancy, Volume 25 (October, 1925), pp. 250-251. 5 The 1918 Regulation 95, Article 52, quoted in Charles J. Gaa, The TaxatiOn 0f Copporate InCome (University of Illinois Press, 1999), p. 98. 150 in the regulations in 1921 and 1929 and has remained substan- tially the same even though at times tax methods have deviated from what is considered "good" accounting procedure. Despite these deviations, it is generally agreed that the acceptance and encouragement of accrual accounting by the tax authorities was a major factor contributing to the development and wide— spread use of the matching concept in the business community. As a result, the groundwork both in theory, such as Paton's popularization and expansion of the entity and going—concern postulates, and in tax regulations and laws was being laid for the ascendancy of the income statement to a position as the primary accounting report for stockholders and other external parties. The only catalyst needed was the previously mentioned fluctuations in prices and the newly emerging investor's view- point. Depreciation Federal tax laws had a noticeable effect upon other ac- counting theories and practices which resulted in an increased emphasis on income accounting. For example, the tax law, more than any other factor, probably was responsible for the change in attitude of the business community with respect to the theory that accrued depreciation of fixed assets was a current expense. Before the 1913 Federal tax law,depreciation, if recorded at all, was widely viewed as a valuation concept.6 Systematic depreciation methods had been devised much earlier than this time. For example, the straight—line, reducing balance, sinking- fund and annuity methods, and the unit cost method were not 6Eldon S. Hendrickson,Accounting Theory (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965), p 31. 151 unknown in 1913.7 After the 1913 tax law, however, deprecia- tion became an important item particularly because it was an allowable deduction for income tax purposes. Paton in commen- ting on this new emphasis on depreciation made the following statement: Before the days of income taxation it was very difficult for the accountant to convince the business man, especially the owner of a small enterprise, that it was important for the Value expiration of his fixed assets be accrued upon his books. Now he appears to appreciate the significance of accrued depre— ciation very clearly, and no urging is required to induce him to book a liberal allowance.8 The subject of the proper accounting for depreciation upon the passage of the 1913 tax law immediately became a question of controversy. The tax laws have consistently required the cost basis employing the straight—line or units 9 Yet, as mentioned above, there were of production methods. those who viewed depreciation essentially as a valuation con— cept. For example, the 1913 law permitted depreciation de- ductions as follows: Section IIB (Individuals) that in com- puting net income for the purpose of normal tax there shall be allowed as deductions: a reasonable allowance for the exhaustion, wear and tear of property arising out of its use or employment in the business.... Section IIB (Corporations).... All losses actually sustained within the year and not compensated by insurance or otherwise, 7Earl A. Saliers, Principles of Depreciation (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1915), pp.’139-173. 8William Andrew Paton, Accounting Theory (Accounting Studies Press, Ltd., 1962, reprint of the 1922 edition), p. 19. 9 The 1959 code allows accelerated methods of depreciation. 152 including a reasonable allowance for de- preciation by usei wear and tear of pro- perty, if any.... The tax law of 1916 left most of the provisions for depreciation as they were in 1913. But the Act of 1918 made one notable change -— it included "a reasonable allowance for "11 obsolescence in addition to exhaustion, wear and tear. Prior to this time it was necessary to dispose of property to claim a loss due to obsolescence. In addition, Article 161, Regulation 95 states: A reasonable allowance for the exhaus- tion, wear and tear and obsolescence of pro- perty used in the trade or business may be deducted from the gross income. For conveni- ence such allowance will be referred to as covering depreciation, excluding from the term any idea of a mere reduction in the market value not resulting from exhaustion, wear and tear and obsolescence. The proper allowance for such depreciation...is the amount which should be set aside for the taxable year in accordance with a consistent plan by which the aggregate of such amounts for the useful life of the property in the business will suffice, with the salvage value, at the end of such useful life to provide in the place of the property its cost, or its value as of March 1, 1913, if acquired by the taxpayer before that date.12 Here the regulations specifically indicate that a deprecia- tion deduction cannot be based solely on declining market value. On the other hand, cost or March 1, 1913 value is deemed the acceptable basis. The Revenue Act of 1929 contained the same provisions with minor exceptions as follows: 10United States Government, Underwood—Simmons Tariff Law, 1913, Regulations 33. 11United States Government, Revenue Act of 1918, Section l2Ibid., Article 161, Regulation 95, underline added for emphasis. 153 Sec.209...(c) The basis upon which depletion, exhaustion, wear and tear and obsolescence are to be allowed in respect of any property shall be the same basis as is provided in subsection (a) or (b) for the purpose of determining the gain or loss upon the sale or the disposition of 'property...13 Section (a) in the above quotation was with the cost basis if the property was acquired after February 28, 1913. Section (b) in the above quotation allowed cost or value at March 1, 1913, whichever is greater. With the exception of the March 1, 1913 value or cost whichever is greater pro- vision, the cost basis for depreciation was clearly expressed. In fact, subsequent tax laws also clearly required the cost basis for the calculation of depreciation. Even though the tax laws consistently required the cost basis for the calculation of depreciation allowances, there exiSted some confusion, at least in early tax laws, among the business community and the tax authorities as to the responsi- bility for ascertaining all the facts necessary to a proper determination of the amount of depreciation. Generally, the tax authorities had prepared the necessary schedules and had been placed in the position of having to demonstrate "clear and convincing" evidence that the taxpayers claim was unreason- able.l” This policy of the Internal Revenue tended to slow the development of accurate and detailed records that had originally been started with the passage of the 1913 law. In February, 1939 the Treasury issued Treasury Decision 9922 which reversed this policy. This decision was clarified and expanded in 1939 13 209(c). United States Government, Revenue Act of 1929, Section 1Eugene L. Grant and Paul T. Norton, Jr., Depreciation (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1999), p. 212. 159 and 1936 as Mimeograph 9170 and issued by the Bureau of In- ternal Revenue. A quotation from the 1936 revision reflected this change in policy: Treasury Decision 9922 approved February 28, 1939, provides that taxpayers claiming deductions from_gross income for depreciation furnish full and complete information regarding (l) the cost or other basis of assets for which depreciation is claimed, (2) the age, condition and remaining useful life of the asset, (3) the proportion of the cost or other basis which has been recovered through depreciation allowances for prior taxable years, and (9) such other informa— tion as may be required to establish the correct- ness of the deduction or to determine the amount of the deduction properly allowable.... One of the principal purposes of Treasury Decision 9922 is to place the burden of proof of the correctness of deductions claimed for 5 depreciation squarely upon the taxpayer,....1 This change in philosophy was the catalyst that was necessary to encourage the recording of depreciation in the accounts on a cost basis. Taxpayers now clearly had the responsibility of keeping adequate accounting records for depreciation based upon cost. M. E. Peloubet, in commenting on T. D. 9922, em- phasized this point when he stated that the "best position for the taxpayer to be in regarding depreciation...is to have a de- tailed record of each item included in his accounts for buildings, machinery and equipment or other depreciable assets showing cost or basis,date acquired, expected life, depreciation written off and all pertinent data." Furthermore, he wrote "the further the taxpayer departs from these conditions the more difficulty he may have in establishing his position."16 The possibility of the 15United States Government, Treasury Department, Office of the Commissioner of Internal Revenue, Mimeograph 9170 (Revised) (Washington, D. C., U. S. Government Printing Office, 19365, p. l. 16M. E. Peloubet "Depreciation Under the Revenue Act of 1939," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 58 (September,1939).pP-l89-185o 155 loss of allowances and the fear of tax suits made the calcu— lation of depreciation based on costs a necessary function to be performed by accountants. In summary, the effect of taxation upon depreciation accounting resulted in the recording of depreciation based on cost. This practice helped to create what Littleton calls the balance sheet dilemma. That is to say, circumstances in the early part of this century, such as rising prices and the wave of mergers and consolidations, resulted in much impor— tance being attached to the balance sheet as a statement of values. But, on the other hand, this emphasis on valuation created problems for the determination of income, i. e. recog- nition of revenue before realization. As a result, the cost basis was deemed more appropriate for income determination. Since the tax laws generally favored the purely cost or outlay methods for income determination, business men tended to adopt them in their accounts. As a result, the status of the balance sheet as a statement of values decreased, whereas, the income statement grew in importance. Inventories One of the most significant features in accounting for inventories or stock in trade has been the emphasis placed upon cost or other input value calculations that are matched against revenue in determining income. This emphasis upon the matching concept placed the accountant in the previously mentioned balance sheet dilemma. Specifically, the matching of cost and revenues resulted in inventory procedures that did not produce the values desired by those using balance sheets for credit purposes. 156 Federal taxation with respect to inventories, among other things such as the growth of the corporation and price fluctuations, was a primary factor influencing this emphasis on the matching concept. Paton, once again, recognized this influence as early as 1922. For example, he stated: The influence of the closing inventory balance upon the exhibits of net incomes... is of such consequence as to call for the most searching scrutiny of inventory prac- tices and an insistence upon the use of rational and accurate principles and pro— cedures. Particularly in these days of serious tax levies upon incomes and profits has the entire inventory process become a matter of the utmost importance to all con- cerned. The business man can no longer be satisfied with an inventory, calculated by the cubic yard, for example,.... 7 Tax laws and various regulations initially favored specific identification of costs with revenues as the method for allocating inventory to cost of goods sold for income determination. But the 1918 regulations accepted the first-in, first—out method of allocating costs between inventories and cost of goods sold.18 The FIFO method was accepted primarily because it yielded a good approximation of the results obtained under specific identification. In addition, it was felt that FIFO combined all elements of profit and recognized them at the time of sale, i. e. it does not permit the recognition of un- realized gains and losses. Furthermore, it resulted in the pre- sentation of ending inventory balances at the most recent cost 19 for balance sheet purposes. This acceptance of the FIFO method 17W. A. Paton, "Valuation of Inventories," Journal of Ac— countancy, Vol. 39 (December, 1922), p. 932. 181918, Regulation us, Article 1532. lgHendrickson, op. cit., p. 269. 157 by the tax authorities tended to favor those who espoused the balance sheet as a statement of values for credit pur— poses. The widespread use of FIFO resulted in various attempts by those advocating the matching concept to point out its inadequacies for use in the matching of current costs with current revenues. For example, a publication by the Ameri- can Institute of Accountants contained a statement that op— posed the traditional belief that the flow of costs should follow the flow of goods: ...it may not be a matter of great importance whether cost of goods on hand is determined on the theory that the first goods in are the first goods to go out, or that the last code in are the first goods to go out. This statement, along with the standard arguments rela— tive to variations in periodic profits resulting from use of FIFO, was employed in attempts to justify the use of the LIFO method. As a result of these efforts the Internal Revenue 21 confirmed in 19u7 Code was changed in 1939 and a Tax Court the acceptance of LIFO. These actions left the door open for all taxpayers to use LIFO in their accounts. The final down— fall of the balance sheet as a statement of values or near value was now completed. The income objective prevailed. 20Examination'of Financial Statements by Independent Public Accountants (New York: AmerICan Institute of Accountants, 1936), p. 3. 21Hutzler Brothers, 8th Tax Court 19, 1997. 158 The Influence of the Securities and Exchange Commission Background The legislation leading to the formation of the SEC in the 1930's was not a spontaneous reaction to the depression. In fact, there is evidence that this legislation had many historical antecedents. Particularly, some contend that the laws were directed toward the financial practices of a pros- perity period rather than those found more often in a depression era.22 Time and time again the financial scandals and mal- practices of the late 1920's were discussed in 1933 and 1939 before the Senate Committee on Banking and Currency by experts in accounting, business and law. In short, the passage of the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1939 reflects the public awareness of the emerging investor's point of view. In addition, not only the specific requirements of these acts were important, but the fear of regulation tended to produce improvements in financial reporting practices. Scope of Federal Securities Laws Commerce Clearing House, Inc. stated in its review of the securities laws: The federal securities laws govern companies that seek to acquire new capital by the issuance of securities to the public, and persons in the business of buying and selling securities....They are designed to protect the interest of investors 22J. R. Taylor, "Some Antecedents of the Securities and Exchange Commission," Accounting Review, Vol. XVI (June, 1991), p. 188. 159 and the public by certain disclosure require- ments and by prohibiting fraud and manipulative practices.2 This statement clearly reflected the fact that the new in- vestor's viewpoint had found expression in legislative acts. The laws required the issuer of securities to make available to potential investors certain information about the issuer and the securities offered including, among other things, the plan of distribution, use of proceeds, capital structure, summary of earnings, organization, affiliations, description of businesses and property, pending legal proceedings, and financial statements.2u The registration requirements as set forth in the laws, particularly with respect to the nature and form of financial statements, indicated the new emphasis accorded the income statement. For example, Schedule A (25) of the Securities Act of 1933 states that: ...a balance sheet as of a date not more than ninety days prior to the date of filing the registration statement showing all the assets of the issuer, the nature and cost thereof, whenever determinable, in such detail and in such form as the Commission shall prescribe, including, surplus of the issuer showing how and from what sources such surplus was created, all as of a date not more than ninety days prior to the filing of the registration statement....25 This statement, although for the balance sheet, implied that the income objective is more significant for at least two reasons. First of all, the reference to assets recorded on a 23Commerce Clearing House, Federal Securities Law Reports (New Jersey: Commerce Clearing House, Inc., 1967), p. 101. 2”Ibid., p. 10a. 25United States Securities Act of 1933, An Act of United States Government, May 27, 1933, Schedule A (25). 160 cost basis, as stated before, was the condition considered necessary for the matching concept. In other words, this view is supported by those who believe that the balance sheet is a residual statement and reflects cost awaiting assignment to revenue. The second point is the reference to the surplus account of the issuer. This also reflected the increased em— phasis on income accounting since it was considered necessary to identify the sources from which a surplus was created. Schedule A (25) referred to the registration require— ment of the income statement as follows: ...a profit and loss statement of the issuer showing earnings and income, the nature and source thereof, and the expenses and fixed charges in such detail and such form as the Commission shall prescribe for the latest fis— cal year for which statement is available and for the two preceding fiscal years, year by year, or ... Such statement shall show what the practice of the issuer has been during the three years or lesser period as to the character of the charges, dividends or other distributions made against the surplus accounts, and as to depreciation, depletion, and maintenance charges, in such detail and form as the Commission shall prescribe,... This quotation is important because it demonstrated the extent the law required income statement data. Information as to depreciation, expenses, and distributions against the surplus accounts was seldom disclosed in published annual reports 27 prior to this time. As a result of the passage of the law companies included this information in annual reports since it was made public by the disclosure requirements contained in the law. As a result, income statement data appeared in annual 26Ibid., Schedule A (26). 27T. H. Sanders, "Influence of the Securities and Exchange Commission upon Accounting Principles," The Accounting Review, Volume XI (March, 1936), pp. 73- 79. 161 reports, corresponding to the emergence of income reporting that was documented in Chapter IV. The Securities Exchange Act of 1939 The Securities Exchange Act of 1939, like the 1933 Act, was designed to protect the investing public. Under this act, registration was necessary by any company that sought to acquire new capital by the issuance of securities to the public. Also, this act required that financial data be kept current by means of periodic reports which are attested to by independent public accountants.28 Under this act, the SEC has broad powers to specify the form and content of financial statements and other reports required to be filed. It has specific authority to require the following: The Commission may prescribe,...., the form or forms in which the required informa- tion shall be set forth, the items or details to be shown in the balance sheet and the earnings statement, and the methods to be followed in the preparation of reports, in the appraisal or valuation of assets and liabilities, in the determination of depre— ciation and depletion, in the differentiation of recurring and nonrecurring income, in the differentiaEion of investment and Operating income,.... 9 The above statement indicated that the SEC had the authority to prescribe accounting procedures and the form of financial state- ments. Also, it seems quite obvious that this authority encom- passed specific areas that are very relevant to a proper matching 28Commerce Clearing House, op. cit., II 20, 332—33. 29United States Securities Exchange Act of 1939, An Act of the United—States Government, June 6, 1939, Section 13 (b). 162 of costs with revenues, i. e. depreciation, recurring and non- recurring items, and differentiation between capital and in- come. But the specific recommendations were essentially left to the accounting profession, even though the latter group was very much influenced by the policies of the SEC. As is now known, the accounting profession developed principles of ac- counting that reflected the attention directed to the income statement. Accounting Series Releases-Regulation S-X The Securities and Exchange Commission in 1937 began a program of publication of opinions on accounting principles for the purpose of contributing to the development of more uniform standards for financial statements. These opinions are contained in the Accounting Series Releases and Regulation S-X which contained the requirements for financial statements filed with the Commission as prescribed under the various acts. On April 25, 1935 the SEC stated its administrative policy with respect to financial statements that reflect the dependence placed upon the accounting profession. In cases where financial statements filed with this Commission pursuant to its rules and regulations under the Securities Act of 1933 or the Securities Exchange Act of 1939 are prepared in accordance with accounting principles for which there is no substantial authoritative sup- port, such financial statements will be presumed to be misleading or inaccurate despite disclosures contained in the certificate of the accountant or in footnotes to the statements provided the matters involved are material. In cases where there is a difference of opinion between the Commission and the registrant as to the proper principles of accounting to be followed, dis- closure will be accepted in lieu of correction of the financial statements themselves only if 163 the points involved are such that there is sub- stantial authoritative support for the practices followed by the registrant and the position of the Commission has not previously been expressed in rules, regulations, or other official releases Of the Commission, including the published Opinions Of the chief accountant. 0 This statement of policy is significant because it enhanced the status of the American Institute of Accountants and its Opinions on relevant accounting issues. Thus, subsequent Opinions on accounting principles, emphasizing the importance of the income statement, by the Institute were carefully re- viewed and heeded by the business community. George 0. May supported this view as was evident in the following passage, even though he believed the formulation Of the Commission was unnecessary: ...Its (SEC) decisions on general account- ing questions have usually been reached after con- sultation with the Institute, its influence on accounting practice in the field Of general busi- ness has undoubtedly been beneficial. However, this benefit has arisen from the enforcement of rules which were laid down prior to its creation, and from strengthening the position of the account- ant in relation to the corporation3 rather than from the formulation of new rules. Summary This chapter was concerned with the influence of taxation and other government legislation on the shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement by external parties. It was concluded that the passage Of the Sixteenth Amendment and subsequent legislation led business men to consider it imperative 30United States Securities and Exchange Commission, "Re- lease NO. 9: Administrative Policy on Financial Statements," Accounting Series Releases (Washington: United States Government Printing Office, 1936), pp. 5-6. ' 31George 0. May, Financial Accounting: A Distillation of Experience (New York: The Macmillan Company, 19933, p. 67. 169 that profit figures be calculated with thngreatest possible degree of precision. As a result, accountants began to focus attention on the determination of periodic income. Federal income taxation encouraged accountants to use the accrual basis for income determination. This led to in- creased attention to the matching of revenues with expenses within a specific time period. Depreciation and inventory accounting for the purpose of calculating taxable income were factors contributing to the external shift in emphasis. The tax laws consistently required depreciation and inventories to be calculated on a cost basis for the purposes of ascertaining taxable income. This led to the adoption Of the cost basis for general accounting and to the balance sheet dilemma, that is, to the controversy between those who felt the balance sheet should represent a statement of values and those who felt it should be based upon cost. The legislation leading to the formation of the Securi— ties Exchange Commission, the Securities Act Of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1939, also was an important force contributing to the external shift, especially in corporate reporting. This legislation was important because it reflected the new investor's vieWpoint and it prompted the accounting profession to undertake extensive research focused on those principles underlying the preparation of financial statements. CHAPTER VII SUMMARY This dissertation is a study in the history of accounting thought and it seeks to identify the nature of the shift in em— phasis from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting report. It also presents the more important forces responsible for this ascendancy of the income statement utilizing an historical approach based upon the interpretation of evidence resulting from the interaction of ideas and events. This historical approach was based upon a philOSOphy of history that emerged in the nineteenth century. The philOSOphy of his- tory that emerged was deemed to be (a) a type of research or inquiry designed to answer questions; (b) an attempt to dis- cover actions of human beings that occurred in the past; (c) a process by which evidence is interpreted; and (d) a means where— by perspective could be provided for making choices today. In applying this philosophy of history the historian is confronted with many problems. There is first the problem Of his raw ma- terials. Much of the past was never recorded. Another problem relates to the fact that bias distorts his view. But bias can be effectively handled by revealing the raw materials used, by explicitly stating the organizational scheme, and by revealing the standards that condition the historian's interpretations. 165 166 In this study old corporate annual reports, selected accounting literature, correspondence and internal income statements from selected companies, governmental publications and legislative acts, and interviews, where appropriate, were the basic raw materials. The organizational scheme was to determine the interrelationships between past ideas and events influencing accounting actions. Under this approach both ex- ogenous and endogenous environmental variables can be related to the study. Contemporary accounting theory was used as a framework for making judgments necessary to interpret past accounting actions that may have contributed to the matching concept as it is known today. It also served as a basis for demonstrating the continued interaction between accounting and economics. Furthermore, contemporary accounting theory was valuable par— ticularly because accounting actions of the past could be viewed through its lens. For example, those forces contributing to the decline of the balance sheet as a statement of values could be easily identified since it was known that the cost principle eventually emerged. The history of accounting, with emphasis on the United States, was briefly traced. Early examples Of rudimentary peri- odic reporting before the famous work of Luca Pacioli in 1999 were noted. The period from Pacioli to 1900 was also briefly covered. The ideas and events that were of particular signifi- cance in this period were the widespread use of the double entry method especially during and after the industrial revolution, the separation of statements from the general ledger, the develop- ment of the essential form of present-day financial statements, 167 particularly the balance sheet, and most important of all the rise of the corporate form Of business organization. The next period examined was that of 1900 and 1929. This period was very important because the groundwork in theory and practice, along with crucial exogenous forces, appeared which were to have a decisive impact on the external shift in emphasis from the balance sheet to the income statement as the primary accounting statement. The theory was popularized by William A. Paton, the practice was that which resulted from the tax laws and the activ- ities of the American Institute of Accountants, especially their Memorandums on Balance Sheet Audits, while the exogenous vari- ables were mainly the fluctuations in prices, the rapid increase in mergers and consolidations, and the increased public owner- ship Of securities. Finally, financial accounting from 1930 to the present was reviewed with emphasis on the 19308. The im- portant factors consisted of the activities of the American Institute of Accountants and the American Accounting Association, the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1939 as administered by the SEC, New York Stock Exchange activ- ities, and the Great Depression. The conclusion reached in Chapters III and IV was that there was essentially two shifts in emphasis from balance sheet data to income statement data. There was an internal or manager— ial shift and an external shift by stockholders, creditors, and other parties outside the firm. The former shift, it was con- tended, probably occurred with the advent of the corporate form of business organization, characterized by the separation of owners and managers, between 1880 and 1925. On the other hand, 168 the latter shift began in the 19208, accelerated in the 19308, and was essentially completed by the early 19908. The internal shift in emphasis was more difficult to document than was the external shift. Information was Obtained in the form of letters, internal income statements, interviews, or combinations of all three from various selected companies. This information related to the nature and extent of internal income reporting prior to the external shift in emphasis. From this information it was concluded that there was no significant internal shift in emphasis in the early 19308. Income reporting was considered very important to management for the purpose Of testing the profitability Of Operations as a guide to future action long before the external shift even before this time. The most probable force that set the chain of ideas and events into motion which led to the emergence of income state- ment data in managerial decisions was the sudden increase in inventions that appeared in England shortly after 1750, even though these inventions were themselves the result Of many complex and remote causes. These inventions helped pave the way for the industrialization of society through the use Of the factory system. It now became necessary to accumulate large amounts Of capital to meet the technical requirements for mass production. In addition, the industrialization of society in— creased the degree Of competition which made survival tenuous at best. As a result, a system based on partnerships or joint— stock companies emerged which has been called Industrial Capi— talism. The great industrial capitalists were specialists of pro- duction rather than finance and followed a social code from 169 the philosophy Of Social Darwinism. Financial mechanisms, such as balance sheets and income statements, were despised by the industrial capitalist. Yet much emphasis was placed on efficiency as measured by the increase in the physical volume of output (e. g. tons of steel). In the last quarter of the nineteenth century the state Of technological progress, the increasing demand for mass produced goods, and the bitterly competitive atmosphere that the industrial capitalists had produced with their ruthless tactics created a need for a new type of business organization. The corporation with its features Of stock ownership, limited liability, transferability of interests, and separation of owners and managers was ideally suited to fulfill this need. The financial capitalist-~the banker, the investment banker, and the insurance company-—initiated the corporate revolution in America. The financial capitalist was not inter— ested in the day-tO—day Operations Of the business since he spread his interests over many different industries. Therefore, managers were appointed to assume this function. As a result, a new professional managerial class emerged. The professional manager was a specialist who depended upon accounting, statistical and economic data in making decisions. Since he was held responsible for his performance and since com— petition was keen, he needed tO test the profitability of Opera— tions as a guide for future actions and did so through the use of cost and revenue data. The development of cost accounting and the work Of the scientific engineers between 1885 and 1930 provided evidential support for this internal shift in emphasis. 170 Furthermore, a survey Of selected companies indicated that profit and loss data were accumulated and used internally long before the external shift in emphasis occurred in the early 19308. The external shift in emphasis was the result of many forces. Like the internal shift, the rise Of the corporation was very important. It prompted Professor Paton and others to focus attention on the entity concept and the_going—concern assumption. The emergence of the investor's viewpoint resul- ting from the rapid growth of stock ownership by the general public resulted in a new demand for information. Investors sought growth as well as the safety of their original invest- ment. The income statement was useful for this purpose be- cause it yielded profit data very essential in analyzing investment alternatives. The rapid fluctuation in the prices Of goods and services that began in the early 19208 left doubt in people's mind as to the adequacy of the balance sheet as a statement of values. But Federal taxation of income and related court decisions were the most important deve10pments contributing to the emergence Of income reporting via the matching concept. Federal tax laws have consistently required the cost basis for such items as depreciation and inventories. This requirement naturally con— tributed to the demise of the balance sheet as a statement and its replacement with a statement of unallocated or residual costs. The courts played a key role in the emergence Of the matching concept because they became involved with the problem Of identifying what was income. In the famous decision of Eisner V. Macomber it was held that income did not exist until 171 it was severed from capital. This meant that for most types of property income could emerge only through the sale or ex- change Of the property. Thus, accountants concentrated on rules and procedures that would identify a severance or sale of assets. As a result the transactions approach to income determination based upon the realization concept emerged. The main lesson to be learned from this study is that accounting evolution involves the interaction Of ideas and events which makes change a permanent feature. It demonstrated the futility of arguing about how progress in accounting pro- ceeds since both practice and theory interact to cause change. Those forces that were considered to be primarily responsible for both the external and internal shift in emphasis involved developments in accounting practice and theory, and exogenous changes in other disciplines. For an appropriate perspective in making decisions one should be cognizant of these forces. For example, it was concluded that one of the major reasons for the external shift was the emergence Of the investor's vieWpOint resulting from the corporate revolution. Investors demanded information that was useful in ascertaining the relative pro- fitability of various investment alternatives. The income state— ment was an excellent means for supplying this information. Today the environment has changed. Corporations have evolved into a new dimension—-conglomerates. No longer is the"conventional" net income as significant to investors. Infor— mation is being demanded concerning the profitability Of divisions and product lines. Once again the SEC is interested in seeing that these new investor demands are met. As a result, the ac- counting profession, if it is to maintain its autonomy, must take 172 an active role in providing the kinds of information demanded. The shift in emphasis also clearly shows the importance of specifying objectives. This involves an understanding of not only the types of information demanded, but also a general knowledge of the groups demanding the information. The con— sequences of emphasizing the creditor vieWpoint in determining the type Of information supplied by accountants were revealed. It was shown that Objectives Of accounting should not only consider creditors but managers and investors and other outside interested parties. BIBLIOGRAPHY. Books American Accounting Association. ‘Accounting and Reporting Standards fOr Corporate Financial Statements and Preceding Statements and Supplements. Columbus, Ohio: American Accounting Association, 1957. American Accounting Association. A Statement of Basic Accoun- ting Theory. Evanston, Illinois: American Accounting Association, 1966. American Institute of Accountants. Audit of Corporate Accounts. New York: American Institute of Accountants, 1939. American Institute Of Accountants. ChangingiCOncepts of Business Income. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1952. American Institute of Accountants. Examination of Financial Statements by Independent Public Accountants. New York: American Institute Publishing Company, 1936. Baldwin, James Mark. Dictionary Of Philosophy and Psychology. New York: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 1955. Blaug, M. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1962. Burns, Edward Mc Nall. Western Civilizations. New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1958. Canning, John B. The Economics of Accountancy. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1929. Chamber, Raymond J. Accounting, Evaluation and Economic Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1966. Clark, John Bates. The Distribution of Wealth. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1899. Cole, William Morse. Accounts, Their Construction and Inter— pretation. New York: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1908. Collingwood, R. G. The Idea of History. London: Oxford Uni- versity Press, Inc. Commager, Henry. The Study of History. Columbus, Ohio: Charles - E. Merrill Books, Inc., 1965. Commerce Clearing House. Federal Securities Law Reports. New York: Commerce Clearing House, Inc., 1967. 173 179 Copi, Irving M.‘ Introduction to Logic, 2nd Edition. New York: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 1961. Corey, Lewis. ’The'House Of Morgan. New York: Grosset and Dunlap. Inc., 1930. Couchman, Chester B.‘ The Balance Sheet. New York: The Jour— nal of Accountancy, Inc., 1823./92o' Davenport, Herbert Joseph. The Economics of Enterprise. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1913. Deinger, Harvey T. DevelOpment of Accounting Thought. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1965. Edwards, Edgar O. and Bell, Philip W. The Theory and Measure- ment of Business Income. Los Angeles, California: University of California Press, 1965. Edwards, James Don. History of Public Accounting in the United States. East Lansing, Michigan: Bureau of Business and Economic Research, Michigan State University, 1960. Edwards, Paul (Ed). The Encyclopedia of Philosophy. New York: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 1967. Fisher, Irving. Elementary Principles of Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1911 Fisher, Irving. The Nature of Capital and Income. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1906. Gaa, Charles J. The Taxation of Corporate Income. University Of Illinois Press, 1999. Galbraith, John Kenneth. The Affluent Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1958. Galbraith, John Kenneth. The Great Crash. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1961 Garner, 8. Paul. Evolution of Cost Accounting to 1925. Univer- sity, Alabama: University of Alabama Press, 1959. General Electric Company. General Electric's Growth. Book One. General Electric Company, 1953. Gide, Charles and Rist, Charles. A History of Economic Doc— trines, 2nd. Edition. New YOrk: D. C. Heath and Com- pany, 1999. Gilman, Stephen.‘ Accounting ConCepts of Profit. New York: The Ronalderess Company, 1939. 175 Goldberg, Louis. An Inquiry into the Nature Of Accounting. Monograph NO. 7; American Accounting Association, 1969. Grant, Eugene L. and Norton, Paul T. Jr. Depreciation. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1999. Grivalli, Pietro. An Original Translation of the Treatise on Double-Entry. New York: Harper Brothers, Inc., n.d. Haney, Lewis H. History Of Economic Thought, 9th Edition. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1999. Hatfield, Henry Rand. Accounting: Its Principles and Problems. New York: D. Appleton and’Company, 1929. Hatfield, Henry Rand. Modern Accounting. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1909. Hawley, Frederick B. Enterprise and the Productive Process. New York: G. P. Putnam's Sons, 1907. Heckscher, Eli F. Mercantilism. 2 vols.; London: George Allen and Unwin, Ltd., 1935. Hendrickson, Eldon S. Accounting Theory. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965. Hicks, J. R. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Funda— mental Principles Of Economic Theory, 2nd. Edition. Oxford: The Clarendon Press, 1950. Hobson, J. A. The Industrial System, an Inquiry into Earned and Unearned Income, Revised Edition. London: P. S. King and Son, Ltd., 1910. Ijiri, Yuji. The Foundations of Accounting Measurement. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1967. Johnson,E. A. and Kroose, Herman E. The American Economy. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1960. Kester, Roy B. Accounting Theory and Practice. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1917. Kester, Roy B. Accounting Theory and Practice. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1930. Keynes, John Maynard. A Treatise on Probability. London: The Macmillan Company, Inc., 1998. Knight, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Kelley and Millman, Inc., reprint of 1921 Edition, 1952. 176 Knoeppel, C. E. OrganiZatiOn and Administration. New York: Industrial Extension Institute, 1921. Kroose, Herman E.‘ American Economic Development. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1962. Littleton, A. C.‘ AcCounting EVOIution to 1900. New York: American Institute Publishing Company, Inc., 1933. Littleton, A. C. 'E88ays on Aeoountancy. Urbana, Illinois: University of IllinOis Press, 1961. Littleton, A. C. ‘Structure of Accounting Theory. Monograph NO. 5; Urbana, Illinois: American Accounting Associ— ation, 1953. Littleton, A. C. and Zimmerman, V.K. Accounting Theory: Con— 'tinuity and Change. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: PrenticeiHall, Inc., 1962. Malthus, Thomas R. Principles of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, Inc., reprint of 1820 Edition,1951. Marshall, Alfred. Principles Of Economics. 8th Edition. London: Macmillan and Company, Ltd., 1920. Marx, Karl. Theories of Surplus Value. G. A. Bonner and Emile Burns (trans); New York; International Publishers, 1952. Mautz, R. K. and Sharaf, Hussein A. The Philosophy of Auditing. Monograph NO. 6; American Accounting Association, 1966. May, George O. Financial Accounting. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1993. McConnell, Campbell R. Economics: Principles, Problems, and Policies, 2nd EditiOn. New York: McGraw-Hill Company, Inc., 1963. McKinsey, James D. Accounting Principles. Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Company, 1929. McKinsey, James D. and Noble, Howard 8. Accounting Principles, 2nd Edition. Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Company, 1935. McKinsey, James D. and Noble, Howard S. Accounting Principles, 3rd Edition. Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Company, 1939. Means, Gardiner C. The Corporate Revolution In America. New York: The Crowell-Collier Publishing Company, 1962. Meek, Ronald L. The EconOmics of Physiocracy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1963. 177 Mill, John Stuart. Principles of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley,71nc., reprint of 3rd} Ed. 1852,1961. Montgomery, Robert H. ’Auditing Theory and Practice. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1912. Montgomery, Robert H. Auditing Theory and Practice, 5th Ed. The Ronald Press Company, 1939. Montgomery, Robert H. Auditing Theory and Practice, 6th Ed. The Ronald Press Company, 1990. Moonitz, Maurice. The Basic POstulates of Accounting. New York: American Institute Of Certified Public Accoun- tants, 1961. Newman, Phillip Charles. The Development Of Economic Thought. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1952. Nicholson, J. Lee. Factory Organization and Costs. New York: Kohl Technical Publishing Company, 1901 Nicholson, J. Lee. Profitable Management. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1923. Nicholson, J. Lee and Rohrback, John F. D. Cost Accounting. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1919. Noble, Howard S. Accounting Principles, 9th Ed. Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing Company, 1995. Paton, William A. Accounting. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1926. Paton, William Andrew. Accounting Theory. Chicago: Accounting Studies Press, Ltd. Reprint Of 1922 Edition, 1962. Paton, W. A. and Littleton, A. C. An Introduction to Corporate AccountingyStandards. Ann Arbor, Michigan: American Accounfing Association, 1990. Perangallo, Edward. Origin and Evolution of Double Entry Book- keeping. NeinorkziAmerican Institute Publishing Com— pany, Inc., 1938. Rappaport, Louis H. S E C Accounting Practice and Procedure. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1956. Ricardo, David. 'The Principles of Political Economy and Taxa- tion. Neinork: E. P. Dutton and Company, Inc., reprint Of 1817 Edition, 1937. 178 Ripley, William Z. 'Main Street and Wall Street. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1927. Ripley, William Z. ‘Railroads, Finance and OrganizatiOn. New York: Longmans, Green and Company, 1915. Saliers, Earl.“ Principles of Depreciation. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1915. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 'History of EconOmic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press, 1959. Sloan, Alfred P. Jr. My Years With General Motors. Garden City, New York: Doubleday and Company, Inc., 1969. Smith, Adam: The Wealth of Nation. Edwin Cannan (ed.) 2 Vols.; New Rochelle, New York: Arlington House, reprint Of 1776 Edition, 1950. Solomon, Ezra. The Theory of Financial Management. New York: Columbia University Press, 1963. Soule, George. Soule's New Science and Practice of Accounts, 7th Ed. New Orleans, Louisiana: unknown, 1903. Sprague, Charles E. The Philosophy of Accounts. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1908. Sprouse, Robert T. and Moonitz, Maurice. "A Tentative Set of Broad Accounting Principles for Business Enterprises," Accounting Re8earch Study NO. 3. New York: American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 1962. Storey, Reed K. The Search for Accounting Principles. New York: American Institute Of Certified Public Accountants, 1969. Taussig, F. W. Principles Of Economics. 2 Vols. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1913. Taylor, Frederick W. The Principles Of Scientific Management. New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1911. Taylor, Frederick W. ShOp Management. New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1911. Turgot, Anne-Robert-Jacques. Reflections on the Formation and Distribution of Riches. New York: The Macmillan Company, reprint Of the 1776 Edition, 1911. Webner, Frank E. Factory Costs. New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1911. 179 Articles 8 Periodicals American Accounting Association. "Accounting Concepts and Standards UnderlyinngOrporate Financial Statements," 1998 Revision, AccOunting Review, Vol. XXII (October, 1998), 339-3uu. American Accounting Association. "Accounting Principles Under- lying Corporate Financial Statements, Accounting Review, Vol. XVI (June, 1991), 133-139. American Accounting Association. "A Statement of Objectives of the American Accounting Association," Accounting Review, Vol. XI (March, 1936), 1-9. American Accounting Association, "A Tentative Statement of Accounting Principles Affecting Corporate Reports," Accounting Review, Vol. XI (June, 1936), 187-191. Bailey, George D. "The Increasing Significance of the Income Statement," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 85 (January, 1998), 10—19. Bowers, Russell. "Tests of Income Realization," Accounting Review, Vol. XVI (June, 1991), 139—155. Brundage, P. F. "Influence of Government Regulation on Develop— ment of Today's Accounting Practices," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 90 (November, 1950), 389:391. Chambers, Raymond J. "The Implications of Assets Revaluation and Bonus Share Issues," Australian Accountant, Vol. 27 (November, 1957), 507-53l. Chang, Emily Chen. "Business Income In Accounting Economics," Accounting Review, Vol. XXXVII (October, 1962), 636—699. Clark, John Bates. "Insurance and Business Profits," The Quarterly Journal Of Economics, Vol. VII (October, 1892), 90-59. Clark, John Bates. "Profits Under Modern Conditions," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. II (1887), 603—619. Daines, H. C. "The Changing Objectives of Accounting," Accoun— ting Review, Vol. IV (June, 1929), 99—110. De Rooner, Raymond. "The Lingering Influence of Medieval Prac- tices," AccOunting Review, Vol. XVIII (April, 1993), 198-151. Donald, A. G. "HistoricalBackground Of Accounting as a Control," TheAccountants' Dige8t, Vol. XXXIII (October, 1967), 8-20. 180 Editorial. "Clear Statements Needed," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 50 (July, 1930), 5—7. Editorial. "Earning Per Share," Journal Of Accountancy, Vol. 99 (May, 1930), 322-329. Editorial. "Fruits of Experiment," Journal Of Accountancy, Vol. 56 (November, 1933), 320-322. Editorial. "Income Defined at Last," Journal Of Accountancy, Vol.95 (February, 1928), 125—127. Editorial. Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 57 (March, 1939), 168-172. Editorial. "The Meaning of a Balance Sheet," Journal Of Ac— countancy, Vol. 96 (December, 1928), 995-996. Editorial. "What Is Income," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 55 (June, 1933), 901-902. Editorial. "What Are Net Profits?," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 97 (January, 1929), 99-97. Garner, S. Paul. "Highlights in the Development Of Cost Accoun- ting," The National Public Accountant (March, 1950),2-l9. Hawley, Frederick B. "Reply to Final Objections to the Risk Theory Of Profits," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV (August, 1901), 603-620. Harrigan, James O. "A Short History Of Financial Ratio Analysis," Accounting RevieW3 Vol. XLIII (April, 1968), 289-299. Hoxesey, J. M. B. "Accounting for Investors," Journal Of Ac— countancy, Vol. 50 (October, 1930), 251-289. Jennings, Alvin R. "Accounting Research," AccountingyReview, Vol. XXXII (October, 1958), 597-559. Kohler, Eric L. "Tendencies in Balance Sheet Construction," Accounting Review, Vol. 1 (December, 1926), 1-11. Littleton, A. C. "Principles of Valuation as Related to the Balance Sheet," Papers and Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Meeting (19237, American AssociatiOn of Univer— sity Instructors in Accounting, 19-15. Littleton, A. C. "Value and Price in Accounting," Accounting Review, Vol. IV (September, 1929), 197-159. May, George 0. "Accounting Concepts and Standards Underlying Corporate Financial Statements," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 86 (November, 1998), 56—61. 181 May, George 0. "Authoritative Financial Accounting," Journal of AcCountancy, Vol. 82 (August, 1996), 102-119. May, George 0. "Business Income," 'The Accountant, VOl.CXXIII (September 30, 1950), 315-323. May, George 0. "Improvements in Financial Accounts," Journal Of Accountangy, Vol. 63 (May, 1937), 333-369. May, George 0. "Taxable Income and Accounting Bases for Deter- mining It," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 90 (October, 1925), 298—266. Miller, Herbert E. "The 1998 Revision of the American Accounting Association's Statement of Principles-~A General Ap- praisal," Accounting Review, Vol. XXIV (January, 1999), ”Li-50 o Paton, William A. "Recent and Prospective Developments in Accounting Theory," in Mary E. Murphy (ed). Selected Readings in Accountingyand Auditing. New York: Prentice- Hall, Inc. 1952. Paton, William A. "Valuation Of Inventories," Journal Of Accoun- tancy, Vol. 39 (December, 1922), 932-950. Peloubet, M. E. "Depreciation Under the Revenue Act of 1939," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 58 (September, 1939), 169-197. Phillips, Edward G. "The Accretion Concept of Income," Accoun- ting Review, VOl. XXXVII (January, 1963), 19—25. Sanders, T. H. "Influence of the Securities and Exchange Commission upon Accounting Principles," Accounting Review, Vol. XI (March, 1936), 66-79. Smart, Jackson W. "Public Accounting Practice in the United States with Particular Reference to Current Problems," The Accountant, Vol. CXIX (August 19, 1998), 129-135. Sprouse, Robert T. "Accounting For What-You-May-Call-Its," Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 122 (October, 1966), 95-53. Taylor, J. R. "Some Antecedents of the Securities and Exchange Commission," Accounting Review, Vol. XVI (June, 1991), 188-196. Thompson, C. Bertrand. "The Literature Of Scientific Management," Quarterlngournal of Economics, Vol. XXVIII (June, 1919), 506-557. Vance, Lawrence. "The Authority of History in Inventory Valua- tion," Accounting Review, Vol. XVIII (July, l993),219-227. 182 Walker, Francis. A. "The Source Of Business Profits," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. I (April, 1887), 265—288. Whitmore, John. "Factory Accounts.a8.App1ied to Machine Shops," Journal of Accountancy, Vols. II 8 III (August, 1906; November, I906), 298-258, 106-119. Windal, Floyd W. "The Accounting Concept of Realization," Accounting Review, Vol. XXXVI (April, 1961), 299-258. Yamey, Basil S. "Accounting and the Rise of Capitalism: Further Notes on a Theme by Sombart," Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. II, (Autumn, 1969), 117—136. Public Documents Eisner V Macomber, 252 (U. S.) 183 (1920). Securities and Exchange Commission, "Release No. 70; Revision Of Regulation S-X," Accounting Series Releases. Washington: United States Government Printing Office, 1956. S. Government. Mimeograph 9170 Revised, 1936. S. Government. Regulation 95. (1918) Article 1582. S. Government. Revenue Act of 1918. Section 219(a-7). Government. Revenue Act of 1929. Section 209 (c). S. Government. Securities Act of 1933. An Act of May 27,1933. CJCICICJCIC‘. U) S. Government. Securities Exchange Act of 1939. An act of June 6, 1939. C'. U) Government. Underwood-Simmons Tariff Law. (1913), Reg. 23. S. Government. Verification of Financial Statements (Revised). Wash1ngton: U.S. Government PrintinglOffice, 1929. U. S. Securities and Exchange Commission. Accounting Series Releases. Wash1ngton: U.S. Government Printing Office. CLIFFORD DEAN BROWN 1969 © ALL RIGHTS RESERVED 03082 1 89 1|l11111111111IUIINUNITIWIMHIUIIWIN