...r.,..a... . . 4..:vI-tvv.4 vvvl wro. V 17". 133-...930 v. :4... ul. 9 v ,V 1' < V! . .4...Y'R1.f'lvrl V4.0 .. I? . 35:34.... .. uyyvnvvrfvrvvn: v.5. .1): . r. :7... .Lca.4.u4. .. o... :1, v. 3.1..r.|.. 11 . r . r51 . c 17 4.....3.!..L.vv\:vlb 4! or. 1’. 1...:afoa v. vtrl. . 1a . 92.11;}. , v. ...a4 1" v.!... . 2.1!. y L 11:25, I, ....4...I(.4.:. .Iv.f.r.:I. .0; pl. rilrvlulf .vu.!”...fa v.“ r! , v;..1l.v.. it!!! .1. {VII .Ivrvfy - . Y: .. 9:5... 3. .1v1:., ..‘er.....-i.v.: $3.722; . ..¢ 1 .v saggy. .4.;"....,. . . . , 7. . 5.. m§05.§6?§u i, \ . .: VA. [v.17 v:v .chthW.” n . v. I. . . ”urn....U.nu(fi...tu.3r,.rn(,r»« . . . . i. . In. Buggfigth‘ 7:} LIBRARY l | Michigan State f University ‘ This is to certify that the thesis entitled w__.- THE EFFECTS OF INFLAT'T‘OM‘ THE DEGREE OF LEVERAGING, AND ACCOUNTING PRACTICES UPON COMMON STOCK PRICES presented by Duncan Cameron Bryan has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for PhoDI degree in FINANCE [JI‘ {‘é;;£4’\ Major professor Date April 30. 1975 0-7639 amozg "3: 1 o MIG l i ABSTRACT THE DEGREE OF LEVERAGING, d .W)\;j? THE EFFECTS OF INFLATION, \ AND ACCOUNTING PRACTICES UPON COMMON STOCK PRICES BY Duncan Cameron Bryan This thesis analyzes the response of investors to the differential impact of inflation upon firms having differing degrees of leveraging and differing accounting practices. Investor reaponse is measured by the relation- ship of common stock prices to historical-dollar earnings from which inflation-induced earnings have been abstracted. In order to pursue this research. a model for true after-tax net nominal earnings (TANNE) was develOped° TANNE are equal to historical-dollar earnings adjusted for earnings resulting from: a net-monetary debtor position9 FIFO inventory valuation. and the underdepreciation of fixed assets when general price—level adjusted accounting is contrasted with historical-dollar accounting. TANNE were incorporated within the framework of a new common stock valuation model, which includes not only characteristics of the individual firm, but also charact- eristics of the market as a whole. This model is an l—'Em"u extension of the works of John B. Williams and David Durand. The explanatory variables in the model include: the firm's current dividend, the firm's expected dividend growth rate, the firm's risk premium, the market's dividend yield, the market's expected dividend growth rate. and the market's risk premium. In order to capture the impact of inflation tests were run on 1965 and 1972 data. 1965 was the final year of a six year period of relative price stability. while 1972 came at the end of a six year period in which the average annual rate of inflation was twice that of the prior period. The major findings of this research are as follows. The coefficients of the relative dividend payout ratio were negative in both of the test years, but signifi- cant only for 1972. These results indicate that investors prefer a lower relative dividend payout ratio or a higher relative earnings retention rate, in an inflationary period. The coefficients for the FIFO inventory valuation holding gains were significant in both of the test years. However. in the relatively low inflation period the sign of the coefficient was positive and in the relatively high inflation period it was negative. These results indicate that in a period of relatively low inflation investors look favorably upon such gains. but in an in- flationary period such gains are discounted by investors. The coefficients of the net-monetary debtor leverage position were negative in both years. and significant only in the 1972 inflationary period. These results indicate that investors tended to ignore a net-monetary debtor position in a period of relative price stability. However, in an inflationary period, specifically 1972. investors viewed a net-monetary debtor leverage position as not enhancing the relative value of the firm’s common stock. These results appear to be at variance with those of Professors R. Kessel and A. Alchian. but may be ex- plained by the four-fold increase in the cost of servicing net-monetary debt per dollar of earnings. The coefficients of the relative historical-dollar accounting earnings were positive and significant in both test years, indicating that investors look favorably upon a relative increase in historical-dollar earnings. The coefficients of the proxy for the underdepreciation of fixed assets when general price-level adjusted accounting and historical—dollar accounting are contrasted were significant in the period of low inflation and not signifi- cant in the inflationary period. The individual values of the lagged coefficients were positive and significant for the most recent three years in both test periods. It would appear that investors looked favorably upon the underdepreciation of fixed assets. This apparent anomaly may have been caused by the inability to specify the replacement variable in the regression model. Thus these findings. rather than revealing investor perception of underdepreciation. may indicate that investors look favorably upon the most recent three year's general price- level adjusted capital spending. The empirical results lend support to the hypothesis that investors were intuitively adjusting historical- dollar accounting earnings for the impact of inflation even before the artificiality of some of these earnings had been brought to general attention. In this way these findings support the efficiency of capital markets. THE EFFECTS OF INFLATION, THE DEGREE OF LEVERAGING. AND ACCOUNTING PRACTICES UPON COIION STOCK PRICES By Duncan Cameron Bryan A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Finance 1975 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to thank those who have provided me with the inspiration and support necessary for the completion of this thesis. I am grateful to Professor Roland I. Robinson for agreeing to serve as Chairman of my Thesis Committee, and for his insightful comments and advice on my work. Professor Harold Sollenberger. as well as serving on my committee, was a source of literary and professionsl help throughout this thesis. I am especially grateful to Professor Robert Rasche without whose enthusiasm and knowledge, my work would not have been completed. I am indebted to Professor William Barnett who undertook to read this thesis. and whose comments were invaluable. To my wife whose faith and editorial ability during a period of ever increasing adversity was a source of constant inspiration. I humbly acknowledge that my wife and daughters gave several years of their husband and father to this work. Finally I would thank Christine. Harvey and Mermum and all those others who have believed in the X factor. ii CHAPTER I CHAPTER II CHAPTER I I I TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION A REVIEW OF PAST STUDIES INFLATIQNNAND A NQNETARY DEBTQN POSITION ENE ACCUNACY OF INFLATIONARY ANTICIPATION ENE ADAPTIVE EXPECTATIONS MODEL INFLATION AND DEPRECIATIQN INFLATION AND FINANCIAL ACCOUNELNQ SUMMARY ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK TRUE AFTER-TAX NET NOMINAL EARNINGS MODEL Model of a World Without Inflation Model of a World With Inflation Common Stock Valuation Model Based Upon Historical-Dollar Accounting Earnings SUMMARY Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page 1 L. 7 24 25 CHAPTER IV REGRESSION MODEL BASED UPON TRUE AFTER-TAX NET NOMINAL EARNINGS REGRESSION MODEL DEVELOPMENT SUMMARY CHAPTER V TESTING THE PRICE RELATIVE REGRESSION MODEL SOURCE AND SELECTION OF DATA PROCEEDURE RESULTS OF ENE STUDY Ngglysis of the Coefficients of the Individual Variables INTERPNETATION OF THE RESULTS The Relative Dividend Payout Ratio The Relative Historiggl-Dollar Accounting Earnings The Differegge Between HiStQEEEEI‘ Dollar and General-Price Level Adjusted Depreciation The Inventory Holding Gain The Net-Monetary Debtor Leverage 3N9 ExpectgggDivigggg,Growth Ratgg The Relative Risk Premium SUMMARY OF FINDINGS APPENDIX DEFINITION OF VARIABLES THE BIBLIOGRAPHY iv Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page Page 87 93 95 95 9? 100 100 102 105 108 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table LIST OF TABLES Page Page Page Page Page Page Page 91 91 93 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION A decade of accelerating inflation has made financial analysts deeply conscious of how the shrinking value of money effects the calculus of economic decision making. Investors are particularily sensitive to this problem because they must make a trade-off between certain consump- tion today and uncertain consumption in the future. Inflation has a variety of influences upon the value of corporate equities; some would appear to be favorable, while others appear to be unfavorable. This study is an effort to sort out these presumptive influences and to bring to bear the powerful tools of statistical research upon these influences. and to give some quantitative measure of their relative importance. This research was stimulated by still one more consideration. Security analysis depends in a large measure upon the financial reports prepared by accountants. During the past decade the accounting profession has been in an unusual period of flux as "generally accepted accounting principles" have been revised, disputed. and revised again. Investors have become more sensitive to the fact that accounting is not an exact science and presumably wish to look more deeply into the impact of inflation upon the 'quality of earnings" as reported by the accountants. This research will investigate investor perceptions of certain financial variaoles as determanents of common stock valuation during an inflationary period. The primary area where inflation might be expected to affect this perception would be in current earnings relative to the previous year's earnings; a focus stimu— lated by investor emphasis upon growth in earnings per share. In addition, investor discrimination between the current dividend payout ratio as compared to the previous year's ratio deserves testing. A second area where inflation might be expected to affect investor perception, is in the difference between real economic and accounting depreciation of fixed assets. Another area where inflation might be expected to affect investor perception, is the earnings attributable to the first-in-first-out (FIFO) inventory valuation method. Still another area where inflation might be expected to affect investor perception, is the degree to which a firm is a net-monetary debtor. Still other areas where inflation might be expected to affect investor perception are the riskiness of the firm and its expected dividend growth rate. In order that firm-size may not be a source of possible distortion. financial data for individual firms will be standardized by dividing these data by the previous year's earnings. This study will require models for inventory holding gains. and for the underdepreciation of fixed assets when historical-dollar accounting is contrasted with general price-level adjusted accounting. Further. it will deveIOp and Specify a common stock valuation model that incorporates the firm's current dividend, the dividend yield for the market as a whole. the expected dividend growth rate of the firm relative to that of the market. and the risk premium of the firm relative to that of the market as a whole. CHAPTER II A REVIEW OF PAST STUDIES The economic literature and more recently the finance and accounting literature have dealt with the potential wealth redistribution due to unanticipated inflation. Economists have Speculated that business firms gain from inflation. Kessel has summarized the three basic transmission hypotheses.1 First, based upon the hypothesis that debtors gain from inflation, and the assumption that business firms are debtors, then wealth will be transferred from creditors to debtor firms if the creditor's inflationary expectations are less than the actual rate of inflation. Firms contract to pay fixed sums of money in the form of debt instruments; inflation will cause a depreciation in the real value of money, i.e. its command over real resources. If this depreciation in the real value of money were not fully anticipated by creditors. when the nominal interest rate 1 Reuben Kessel, "Inflation Caused Wealth Redistribution: A test of a Hypothesis." American Economic Review. vol. 66 (March 1956), pp. 128-I5I. on the debt was established, creditors would lose and debtor firms would gain.2 Fisher took the position that wealth redistribution clearly took place through this debtor-creditor mechanism: "When prices are rising, the rate of interest tends to be high but not so high as it should be to compensate for the rise; and when prices are falling, the rate of interest tends to be low, but not so low as it should be to compensate for the fall".3 Second, based upon the assumption that nominal wages lag behind prices during an inflationary period, worker's real wages decline while business firms are in a position to raise prices. Thus firm's earnings would be relatively higher during periods of inflation and wealth would be transferred from wage earners to business firms.“ However, serious doubt has been cast upon the validity of this hypothesis by the empirical studies of Alchian and Kessel,5 2 J.M. Keynes, Tract on Monetary Reform, London: MacMillan Co., 1923, p. 18. 3 I. Fisher, The Purchasing Power of Money, New York: MacMillan Co., 1920, pp. 58-73, 190-191. 4 E.J. Hamilton, "Prices as a Factor in Business Growth," Journal of Economic History, vol. XII. (Fall, 1962), pp' 325-31‘90 5 Armen Alchian, Reuben Kessel. "The Meaning and Validity of Inflation - Induced Lag of Real Wages Behind Prices," American Economic Review, vol. 50 (March, 1960), pp. U3-66. Bach and Ando,6 and Felix.7 Third, firms may increase real profits in an inflationary period due to inventory holding gains. This hypothesis assumes that inventories are sold at prices that reflect a mark-up based upon current prices rather than based upon historical costs.6 However, there is no real gain or loss in terms of real resources as a consequence of inflation. As Kessel stated: "Reported business profits may appear larger . . . . However, this is purely an artifact of the original cost accounting."9 The proposed study will not pursue the wage-lag hypothesis, but will concentrate on the debtor-creditor hypothesis and the apparent increase in nominal income due to inventory holding gains in an inflationary period. 6 G.L. Bach, A. Ando, "The Redistributional Effects of Inflation," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 37 (February, 1957), pp. 1-13. 7 D.E. FEliX. ”Profit Inflation and Industrial Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 70 (August, 1956), pp. EEILU63. 8 J.M. Keynes, gp.cit., pp. 18-19. 9 R. Kessel. gp.cit., p. 129. INFLATION AND A MONETARY DEBTOR POSITION 10 and Graham,11 found that the real Bresciani-Turroni, value of bank stocks declined during inflations, and that stock price indexes rose at most only about as much as the 12 attempted to evaluate the rise in price indexes. Kessel Keynes-Fisher hypothesis, that monetary debtors gain from inflation, in terms of stock price movements and to ration- alize his findings with those of Bresciani-Turroni and Graham. Kessel used four random samples of industrial firms, each from those listed on the New York Stock Exchange, and one non-random sample of 16 firms in the banking industry. He classified firms as either net-monetary debtors or net-monetary creditors based upon whether their monetary liabilities were greater than their monetary assets. Monetary assets were defined as an asset whose market value is unaffected by changes in the level of prices. He included in monetary assets: cash, marketable securities, accounts receivable, tax refund receivable, notes receivable, prepaid insurance and gold. Marketable securities required the determination of the net-monetary position of each of the firms these securities represented. 10 Bresciani-Turroni, Economics of Inflation, London: MacMillan Co., 1937, pp. 253, 29 . 11 F.D. Graham, Exchange Prices and Production in Hyper- Inflation: Germany 1920-23, Princeton, 1930, pp. 7h, 177. 12 R. Kessel, gp.cit. In view of these difficulties he assumed that prior to 1930 these securities represented monetary assets and that after 1930 they were monetarily ”neutral" - neither monetary assets nor monetary liabilities. Direct invest- ments in other firms were considered monetarily ”neutral". Monetary liabilities were defined as liabilities whose amount would be independent of changes in the level of prices. Monetary liabilities included: accounts payable, notes payable, tax liability reserves, bonds and preferred stock. Convertible and participating preferred stocks, while income dependent to some degree, were included as part of the monetary liabilities. Using beginning of the period balance sheet data, Kessel found that the increase in the market price of the common stock of net-monetary debtor firms was greater than the increase in common stock price of net-monetary creditors in two overlapping inflationary periods: 1939-1948 and 1942- 19h8. Using the Mann and Whitney test for differences in random variables Kessel found an indicated difference at a level of significance of less than .0025.13 Rank correla- tion testing was also used and yielded results which were significant at the .002 level (R2 = .47). An additional test during a deflationary period 1929-1933 was made and as hypothesized, the market price of net—monetary creditor 13 Ibid., p. 135. firms outperformed that of net-monetary debtor firms at significance levels of .05“ and .03.1u The 16 banking firms were tested using rank correlation based upon the relative net-monetary creditor status, as all firms were found to be net creditors during the 1942-1948 period, and the relative percent increase in each firm's stock price. "Roughly 23 percent of the observed variation was explained by the debtor-creditor hypothesis.”15 Kessel concluded that net-monetary debtor or creditor position had a significant impact upon stock prices in periods of both inflation and deflation. but Kessel questioned the Keynesian assumption that industrial firms were net-monetary debtors. He further concluded that since many industrial firms were not monetary debtors that any stock market index would be composed of both monetary debtors and creditors. The performance of the stock market index as compared to the price index would be a function of the percentage of net—monetary debtors compris- ing the stock market index, and thus, it might not reflect the change in price levels, thereby confirming the findings of Bresciani-Turroni and Graham. 1n Ibid., p. 137. 15 Ibid., p. 132. 10 De Alessi,16 using data from a study by Alchian and 15 found that in Kessel,17 and from a work by Broussalian, 1915 94 percent of the firms studied were net-monetary debtors: by 1934 this percentage had dropped to 54 percent and by 1952 the percentage was 57 percent. De Alessi's conclusion was that: ”Like any other economic unit, a business firm will gain from any unanticipated inflation only in preportion to its net debtor position and the evidence indicates "19 that all business firms are not net debtors. Bach and Ando20 analyzed a random sample of 52 firms over the 1939-1952 inflationary period. They performed rank correlation testing using net-monetary debtor or creditor rank and the increase in stock prices over three sub periods. Their highest rank correlation coefficient was .26 and Bach and Ando concluded that: "These results do not confirm the prediction that debtor companies will gain more during inflation than 16 Louis de Alessi, "Do Businesses Gain From Inflation," Journal of Business, vol. 37 (April, 1964), pp. 159-166. 17 Armen A. Alchian, Reuben Kessel. "Redistribution of Wealth Through Inflation," Science, vol. 130 (Sept. 4, 1959): pp° 535‘539- 18 V.A. Broussalian, "Unanticipated Inflation: A Test of the Debtor-Creditor Hypothesis," Unpublished Ph.D. ’ dissertation, University of California. Los Angeles, 1961. 19 De Alessi, gp.cit., p. 166. 20 Each, Ando, gp.cit., p. 9. 11 will creditors, for any of the sub periods shown, the results are mixed, and over all show no very significant differences.”21 Alchian and Kessel22 made a more comprehensive study of all industrial firms whose common stock was traded on the New York Stock Exchange at any time between 1914 and 1952. They incorporated in their study a new measure of net-monetary debtor or creditor status - the ratio of net-monetary debt to the market value of the firms' common stock. They employed a t test for differences between the means of the relative market value of debtor and creditor firms, adjusted for stock Splits and dividends and assumed that all cash dividends were continuously reinvested in the firm. Their tests for various sub periods which included both inflation and deflation constitute in their words ”overwhelming evidence in support of the Keynes-Fisher reasoning about the bias in interest rates during inflation."23 THE ACCURACY OF INFLATIONARY ANTICIPATION 24 De Alessi constructed a model which is designed to measure the degree of accuracy with which inflation is 21 1.12.1.2” p. 10 22 Alchian, Kessel. 22-213}: p- 535- 23 Ibid.. p- 539- 2# Louis de Alessi, “The Redistribution of Wealth by Inflation: An Empirical Test With U.K. data,” Southern Economic Review, vol. 3 (October, 1963), pp. 113-127. 12 anticipated. The firm's monetary debtor position was established in a manner similiar to that of Kessel.25 Mt E MLt - MAt Mt = Net monetary debtor position. MLt ‘ Monetary liabilities. MAt = Monetary assets. He then defined net non-monetary position as the difference between non-monetary assets (land, buildings, inventory) and non-monetary liabilities (depreciation and maintenance). R ' NMA t _ - NML R Net non-monetary position, t t i.e. net real assets. NMAt = Net non—monetary assets. NMLt Net non-monetary liabilities. Nominal wealth, wt, was then defined as the difference between net non-monetary position (net real assets) and net-monetary debtor position. W 5 R t - M t t De Alessi then excludes all other wealth-affecting factors except "normal income under conditions of static equilibrium” so that net real assets, Rt’ grow at some normal income rate, r, which is termed the real rate of interest. Net monetary liabilities, Mt' grow at the 25 R. Kessel, gp.cit., p. 114. 13 contractually specified interest rate, m.26 De Alessi assumes that m = r. Thus: wt+1 ' "t ’ rO Negative eXposure means: (MA-ML + FX(t))KFX(t) As measured by the median increase in stock values positive exposure firms did 23 percent and 111 percent better than the negative exposure firms in the 1955-1957 and 1965-1970 inflationary periods, while in the 1958-1964 period of price stability positive exposure firms outperformed negative exposure firms by 148 percent using median stock values. While these values indicate a weak confirmation of the debtor-creditor hypothesis, it is believed that 20 the stringency of the negative exposure criterion elimin- ated all but the strongest net debtor firms, and reclassi- fied the less strong net debtor firms as positive exposure firms.”O INFLATION AND FINANCIAL ACCUUNTING The inclusion of depreciation in a wealth redistrib- ution model is significant because George Terborgh has estimated that 20 percent of reported corporate profits since World War II were "paper" profits due to under- depreciation of fixed assets in inflationary periods.“1 Bach and Stephenson recognized "the overstatement of real profits because of inflation-induced increases in stated inventories", but did not include them "because satisfactory data were unavailable for individual firms".l+2 “3 Rosenfeld reviewed a field test in which 18 U.S. companies restated their financial reports for 1966 and 40 If a tax rate of 50 percent is assumed, to qualify as a negative eXposure firm the firm's net monetary debtor position must be at least 50 percent of the firm's net fixed assets. This criterion would lead one to expect a substantial reduction in the impact of net debtor firms in any test. While 89 percent of the firms were net debtor firms in their initial tests, only 30 percent of the firms analyzed by positive and negative eXposure were negative, i.e. very strongly net debtor. 41 George Terborgh, Essays in Inflation, Washington, Machinery and Alli3d Products Institute, 1971, pp. 53-54. 42 Bach, Stephenson, gp.cit., p. 7. 43 Paul Rosenfeld, "Accounting For Inflation: A Field Test," Journal of Accountancy, (June, 1969), pp. 45-50. ,7i,fl___.___________‘_ _ F..- 7.. _, ____., 21 1967 on the basis of "general price level accounting”. The impetus for this test may be found in the minutes of the Accounting Principles Board, April 28, 1961: "the assumption in accounting that fluctuations in the value of the dollar may be ignored is unrealistic". Further, ARS #6 maintained that "general price-level financial statements should provide a basis for a more intelligent, better informed allocation of resources".uu Rosenfeld states that general price-level financial statements: "are based on the same generally accepted accounting principles as conventional ("historical-dollar") financial statements except that changes in general purchasing power are recognized. All items in the restatements are given in a unit of measure which represents the same amount of general purchasing power. . . . Assets are restated at cost not at current value in general price level balance sheets. Cost is restated for changes in the general purchasing power of the dollar, but not for changes in specific prices of assets." 45 Rosenfeld singles out three areas that are eSpecially prone to historical-dollar distortion during inflationary periods: Inventory holding gains as a result of using first- in-first-out inventory valuation. Underdepreciation of assets based upon historical-dollar costs. General price gains and losses, which result from holding monetary assets and liabilities, that are not reported in historical- dollar accounting financial statements. 44 "Reporting the Effect of Price Level Changes," Accounting Research Study #6, American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, New York, 1963, p. 16. 45 Rosenfeld, gp.cit., p. 45. 22 SUMMARY While these previous studies made a valuable contrib- ution to the body of knowledge concerned with wealth redis- tribution during periods of inflation, they indicated areas that require further analysis. This study, building upon the foundation of this previous work, will focus on net-monetary debt per dollar of earnings, the relative dividend payout ratio, under- depreciation of fixed assets when general price-level adjusted and historical-dollar accounting earnings are contrasted, and on the effects of FIFO inventory valuation. CHAPTER Ill ANALYTICAL FRAMEWUKK In this chapter a mocel Will be formulated for true after-tax net nominal earnings, TANNE. This model will incorporate the inflationary effects upon historical- dollar earnings of: general price—level adjusted accounting depreciation, inventory holding gains and a net-monetary debtor position. Further, a common stock valuation model will be formulated that incorporates: the firm's current dividend, the dividend yield of the market as a whole, the expected dividend growth rate of the firm relative to that of the market as a whole, and the risk premium of the firm rel- ative to that of the market. 23 an TRUE AFTER-TAX NET NUMINAL EARNINGS MODEL Given the following balance sheet: Cash (C) Total Current Liabiliities (C/L) Marketable Securities (MS) Long Term Debt (LT) Accounts Receivable (A/R) Preferred Stock (PF) Inventories (IN) Boox Value Equity (8) Total Current Assets (C/A) Net Fixed Assets (FX) Total Assets (PA) Total Liabilities a Equity (TLE) TLE = TA C/L + LT + PF + s = C/A + &x Add and subtract IN from the right hand side. C/L + LT + p? + b = C/A - IN + FX + IN B = (C/A - IN) - (C/L + LT + PF) + (FX + IN) The first term on the right hand side represents the firm's Monetary Assets (MA). The second term on the right hand side represents the firm's Monetary Liabilities (ML). The third term on the right hand side represents the firm's Real Assets (RA). B 3 MA - ML + FX + IN B = FX + IN - (ML - MA) Let Net-Monetary Liabilities, M = ML - MA B = FX + IN - M at time: t = 0 Bo ‘ FXO + INO - MO 25 Model of a World Without Inflation Under conditions of static equilibrium, in a world without risk, the real assets of the firm will grow at some normal real rate of return, r. The firm's net- monetary liabilities will grow at a real rate of interest, m, which is contractually Specified. In a Wicksellian equilibrium m = r, because if m<:r the firm would continue to expand (contract) its stock of capital until the marginal revenue equals the marginal cost. The normal gross real income for the firm, Y1, in period 1, will be the difference between real asset growth and net monetary liability growth. Y1 = r(FXo +INO) - m(MO) In a world with risk, the real assets of the firm will grow at some risk adjusted nominal rate of return, r = r + w w = a risk premium. The net-monetary liabilities of the firm will also grow at some risk adjusted nominal rate of return, mr. m=m+w I‘ 0 Thus gross nominal income, Y1, will be: Y1 = rr(FXO + INO) - mr(MO) In addition, there is a depreciation accounting (affect which will decrease the gross nominal income. 26 The depreciation accounting effect would be some function of the gross fixed real assets, a-(GFXI). Where a 3 g(L.DM) L = The average life of depreciable real assets. The longer the average life of the depreciable real assets, the lower will be the depreciation charge per period and the higher will be the nominal income per period. DM = The accounting depreciation method adOpted by the firm. The straight line method, in lieu of the accelerated methods, will result in a lower initial depreciation charge and thus higher nominal income for the period if the installation of real assets has been at a constant or increasing rate in the past. The actual depreciation rate, DR, will reflect the combined effects of both L and DM. Thus: a = DR1 DR1 = The depreciation rate in period 1. But: DP 2 1 z . . . DRl EFYl DP1 The depre01ation charge in period 1. SO: DP1 a " GFx1 And: IJPl 27 Thus the depreciation adjusted gross nominal income, I. Y1 . will be! 0. Y1 = rr(FXO+INO) - DP1 - mr(MO) In a world with government, there will be taxes, 61' which Will reduce the depreciation adjusted gross nominal income, Y1 . .0: Y1 * rr(FXO+INO) - 0P1 - mr(Mo) - 01 Model of a World With Inflation Assume that all prices increase at some rate K1 the next period. I - I Where K1 = —l———- I = An appropriate price index. Then, in equilibrium, the real assets of the firm must grow at a nominal rate r = rr + K1. The value of the real assets. Let F rr = The risk adjusted nominal rate of return in a period of no inflation. X = The normal real return on real assets. rr(F) = X Assume that the normal income stream grows at 1 + K1 in order to maintain the real return on real assets, and that the real assets grow at 1 + K1 in order to main- tain their real value. Then the nominal rate of growth of 28 0 real assets, r , is: . (1+K1)X + (1+K1)F — F 2 I.“ I‘ (1+K1)X =—-—-F1—-——+1+K1-1 Substitute: rr(F) = X : (1+K1)rr(f") r " F +K1 (1+Kl)rr + K1 = rr + Klrr + K1 but Klrr’Y 0 if both K and rr take on small values. Thus the rate of return on FXO+INO must grow at a D nominal rate r = r + K1 while the book value of the net- r monetary liabilities would not be affected by the price increase of K1 per period. However, the embedded money rate of interest, mp, is the sum of the risk adjusted real rate of interest rr plus the creditor's previous expect- ations about the then rate of anticipated inflation, KP. mp = rr + Kp Given inflation, the nominal earnings, T1, would be: /\ - Y1 = (rr+K1)(FXO+INO) - DPl - mp(MO) - G1 It is further hypothesized that the depreciation accounting effect upon the nominal earnings will be modified by the rate of inflation, K1. — Vifiw———__—_.-H.—¢- ,4", _ .._.__ m. _._,-_.. .,-.~ 29 The nominal earnings under conventional historical— dollar accounting are greater than they would be under general price-level adjusted accounting. This overstatement of nominal earnings results from the fact that the deprecia- tion charge is understated as compared to the depreciation charge under general price-level adjusted accounting. Rosenfeld“6 has indicated that to capture the full impact of this underdepreciation, assets should be restated under general price-level accounting to reflect the actual inflation since their acquisition. Under general price-level accounting: Let: GFXl N The general price-level adjusted ' gross fixed assets at the end of period 1. CS. = The capital Spending, to acquire th fixed assets, in the i period. x? j i = The general price-level adjusted fixed assets acquired in period j, that are retired in period i. j i = The percentage of fixed assets acquired in period j that are re- tired in period i. 46 Paul Rosenfeld, gp.cit., p. 45. 30 At the end of period 1. 1 cs .75 GFX]: z: 11 E _l .. Ll) =-OO( 1 I1 Ii Sci Lb It Lb ,1: - , l ' i l 1 —I(=_°o:—-1—>+(—-—> 1 l Il Ii 11 11 O . ”.V ' '—l 0;). ;K‘ = __i _ 4.1—1 GFXO Io izzgphi 11) o I : AGFX = GI‘Xl '- GFXO =-00( o l i I1 0 “V (35- -R- l I] l ‘ "’ z (11 ‘ 10)). =-00(I - I, )+ (’bl - R1 1. 1 Under historical-dollar accounting: Let: GFX1 = The historical-dollar gross fixed assets at the end of period 1. CS.l = The capital Spending to acquire fixed assets in the ith period. jRi = The assets that were acquired in period j that are retired during period i. in = The percentage of fixed assets acquired in period j that are retired in period 1. 31 1 = Z: \-‘ _ Where 1 R. a -E: - CS. J 1 J ="OOJXI ( J) a . _ L . _ __ 9—. fl = 24 .. ero i =..,Q(tsl 3R1) [)GFX = CFXI - GFXO Historical-dollar accounting, compared to general price-level accounting, understates the change in gross fixed assets in period 1 by: O ’V n Cb ”R v .. W. = .. __l .— -l]———l ‘ .- O 'V —n CS -R- z _ 2... __1. _ .1; _ (11 IO) 1 :-wD “1 I-3’ -3X1 1-3 Let: OX0 =-1X n-ZX-Z x-jX-B 80...: X .8 0X1 8 -1X0 = - 25:1 . 43-2 " 4:3 3 """ 3 3 B1 4&1 ‘ -2Xo g -3b:1 ' -4g-2 z ~5513 -n-2X-n 3 B2 Where Bh is the percentage of the period's capital Spending that is replaced h periods later. Then when: i=1, AGFX' - AGFX -= o . CS0 CS0 120: AGFX " AGFX 3 (I1 " IO)(1 " 80)”?- “(Il - IO)B1T O O i- -1.liGFx -zchx = (11 - 10)(1 - Bl - Boy—f—' -1 cs_1 - (11 - I-1)B2 “T:I 30 cs ._ ' .. = _ \ _ . _ -2 1- 4’2:ch use“ (11 101(1 :52 51 so) 1-2 cs_2 ‘ (11 ‘ 1-2)B3 I_2 ' 1: -3) AGFX 4;de =(I1 - IO)(1 - 53 - 82 - B1 - BO) (L5 . (35 '5 _ - __:l ‘1’; (11 I-flbu I_3 In the generalized form this reduces to: . __...‘ (lsJ‘ i . . w _ 1 AQFX ‘AGFA - 2. T:— (ll-loHl-hizo:bn)-bl_i(ll-Ii)] i=0 Substituting K1 . "“3 CS1 i AGFX - AGFX 2 Z ‘I— (K110)(l-hz Bh)-Bl_i(IO(1+Kl)-Ii)-] 1:0 1 =0 The change in gross fixed assets is understated in 9 period 1 by ZIGFX - [iCFX, and thus the depreciation in period 1 will be undercharged by: ADP/1 = i)R1(AGFX -AGFX) Then: 0 U let K1(1)}'1) = 11k1(AG£~‘x - AGFX) o . A Thus the nominal earnings, Y1, are overstated by 0 A: K1(DP1). Net nominal earnings, Y1, would be: A' ‘ ' - Y1 - (rr+K1)(PAO+INO) - 0P1 - K1(DP1) - mp(MO) - G1 In a period of inflation there may be an increase in the net nominal earnings due to an historical-dollar 37 inventory accounting effect. This inventory accounting effect would be due to the differential impact of inflation upon the cost of goods sold. If the last-in first-out (LIFO) method of inventory valuation is adopted the major portion of the inflationary impact will be reflected in the cost of gooas 8010. However, if the first-in-first-out (FIFO) valuation methOd is adopted a much smaller portion of the inflationary impact will be embodied in the cost of goods sold. It is this differential effect of historical- dollar valuation upon net nominal earnings in a period of inflation that we would like to examine. It is hypothesized that this differential accounting effect is some function of the real inventory, C(FXO). Where: c = V1(j"(T1.K1)) V1 = The inventory valuation method. If the firm is on LIFO there will be no differential accounting effect upon net nominal earnings. 1f the firm is on FIFO there will be an increase in net nominal earnings. Thus V1 is a dummy variable such that: V1 0 if ldfl) II VI 1. if FIFT) T1 = The inventory turnover rate, the cost of goods sold divided by the initial inventory, will effect the differential net nominal earnings. As the inventory 38 turnover increases the change in net nominal earnings per inventory turnover will decrease. However, as the inventory turnover increases the change in differential net nominal earnings will increase at a decreasing rate. K1 = The rate of inflation, the greater the rate, the greater will be the increase in differential net nominal earnings. The differential net nominal earnings effect due to the inventory valuation method would be develOped as follows: Let: YF = Nominal income with FIFO inventory valuation. YL ' Nominal income with LIFO inventory valuation. = Sales for the period. S C = The cost of goods sold using FIFO valuation. C L = The cost of goods sold using LIFO valuation. YF = S - CF YL = S - CL YF-YL=AY=s-L -S+CL II 0 [iY L - LF To approximate the functional relationship between K1 and T1, we assume the following: a. That production and sales are deveIOped at an even rate within the period. 39 b. That the rate of inflation, K1, is constant within the period. Assume an inventory turnover rate, T1 8 1 End End Period 0 Period 1 I Q ' 3 _ - _ II- Klpo Fig. 1 INo I IEPO q0 q0 COGSF ‘ INo COGSL a I + II (see Fig. 1) K cocs - p q + F q (—1) L o o o o 2 K1 3 P0q0(1 4 2—) K1 3 INO(1 + 5—) [XY ' COGSL - COGSF K1 ‘ INO(1 + 5—) - INO K1 8 INO(1 + 2_ - 1) 40 Now assume an inventory turnover rate, T1 = 2 End End Period 0 Period 1 . l I IV K P ————————— 1 o . Fig. 2 INO I 1 III 3P0 qo qo qo COGS = INo + I + II (see Fig. 2) IN + P + P (i) Ei o oqo oqo 2 2 ll K1 3‘ ZINo + INO(E_) K1 ' INO(2 + IT) COGS - I + II + III + IV (see Fig. 2) = I + III + (II + IV) 1 poqo + Poqo + Po(2qo)(2)K1 ' 2Poqo + Poqo (K1) 3 INO(2+K1) K [32' = IN0(2+K1) - INO(2 + 5;) z IN0(£ K1) 41 Thus: . .1. 1 c x v1(x1(1 - ETI)) 1 C(INO) a V1(K1(1 ’ ETI))(INO) Where V1 = 0 if LIFO V1 1 if FIFO Thus earnings for the period would be increased by this differential historical-dollar inventory accounting effect during an inflationary period. However, to obtain adjusted net nominal earnings, $1., this differential historical-dollar inventory accounting effect must be subtracted. To accommodate the effect of taxation, later in this study, the differential historical-dollar inventory accounting effect will be both added and subtracted from the adjusted net nominal earnings. Thus: A" ' 1 Y1 = (rr+K1)(FXo+INO)-DP1-K1(DP1)+V1(K1)(1 - 2T;>INO - V1(K1)(1 - §%—)INo-m (M ) - G1 1 P ° Substituting hp = rr + Kp in the 6th term R.H.S. fun 0 3 1 11 (rr+K1)(FX0+INo)-DP1—K1(DP1)+V1(K1)(1 - ETI)IN0 1 - 42 Au: 0 Y1 * rr(FXo+INO)+K1(FXO+INO)-DP1-K1(DPI) +V1(K1)(1 - 5%?)INO-V1(Kl)(1 - 2%?)INo-rr(mo) -Kp(MO) - 01 Combining terms: ‘Ii' = rr(FXO+INO-MO)+K1(FXO+INO)-DP1-K1(DP;) +V1(K1)(1 - 5%73IN0-V1(K1)(1 — f)_%I.—-)INO-K (Mo) - c1 1 1 p But FXO+INO-MO = s substituting in the 1St term R.H.S. 0 A0: - w ; I ..-' 1 - v (K )(1 - —$—)IN -K (M ) - G 1 1 2T1 o p o 1 But FXO+INO = BO+MO substituting in the 2nd term R.H.S. A00 .— P . ' I 1 . Y1 = rr(bo)+K1(50+M0)-UP1-hl(UPl)+v1(Kl)(1 ' ETI)INO 1 - - V1(K1)(1 - 2T;>INO-Kp(MO) - G1 /\00 _ ' 1 Y1 “ rr(BO)+K1(BO)+K1(M0)“DP1’K1(DP1)+V1(K1)(1 - ETI)INO - v (K )(1 - -l—)IN -K (M ) - G 1 1 2T1 O p o 1 Combining terms: A00 - . _ t 1 1 - . - V1(K1)(1 ‘ ETI)INO+K1(MO)-KP(MO) ' 01 “3 But KP 8 ap - rr substituting in the 7th term R.H.S. A00 - 0 1 1 ' - _ V1(K1)(1 - 2T?)INO+K1(M0)-(mp-rr)Mo - G1 Combining terms: A. U _ v ’ . O 1 1 . . - ’ "1(K1)(1 ’ ETI)I“OI(rr*‘1)Mo‘mp(Mo) ‘ G1 The taxes, 61' are a function of historical-dollar accounting nominal earnings, and not a function of adjusted net nominal earnings. Thus: 1 _ - 1 —* . ‘ cl - t1[(rr+k1)BO-Dpl+vl(kl)(1 - ETI)INo-mp(LTO)J Where: m; = The embedded cost of debt. LT0 = The amount of debt outstanding in period 0. Thus: _._co C_F.dh i 'do mp LTD 0 ixe c arges n perio . PDQ = Preferred Dividend in . d . And: perio O - Co + PDo PFC = Preferred stock at redem- m _ p - LTo + PFO tion value in period 0. 44 Divide numerator and denominator of each term R.H.S. by LTO. $1532 Eo_+§32 a : LTO L O : LTO LTO p TO + Pro 1 + PFO LTO LTO LTO But: -‘I'_CO mp LTD 00! PD '7" +-—TO' a = p ”0 p PFO 1 *T h 0 Or: PF PD - o - o m (1 + ———) = m 7—— P LTO p LTO PF PD -*=_ 0‘ 0 mp mp(1 + __.LTO/ LT Multiply through by LTO: _* _ PFC PDQ . mp(LTO) = mp(1 + 15;)(LT0) - IT; (LTO) = mp(LTO) + mp(PFO) - PDO 45 NOW: M0 = MLO - MAO = LT + CLO + PFC - (CAO - INC) 0 MLO = Monetary liabilities. MAO = Monetary assets. CLO = Current liabilities. CAO = Current assets. 30: . z . _‘. _-p , - , uTO MO (4.140 {'1 0+(CAO 1N0) And: .4? _ 1‘ . '_‘ .. .1 - ‘ mp(LTO) - mpiNO-(buo+rfo-CAO+INO)Jtmp(PPO) FDO = mp(MO)-mp(CLO+PFO-CAO+INO-PFO)-PDO = mp(MO)-mp(CLO-CAO+INO)-PDO Then: I: .. . . 1 .. _ . 1 - +mp(CLO-CAO+INO)+PDOJ 46 Substituting for G1: AI. _ , ' 1 Y1 - (rr+K1)BO-UP1-K1(UP1)+V1(K1)(1 “ ETI>INO v 1 —l—‘ y M ' (M ‘ t r( k ' - 1(K1)( - 2T1)I‘o+(rr+K1) o-mp ‘0)‘ 1L rr+ 1)bo —DP1+V1(Kl/kl - 2T )INO-mpkMO)tmp(ULO*CAO+INO)+PUO{j ‘tl(mp)(ChO‘CAO+lNO)‘tl(PU )‘K1(DP1) —v (y )(1 - —l—)IN +(r +K )M 1 ‘1 2T1 o r 1 o In order to develOp true after-tax net nominal earnings available to common stock holders 81' preferred dividends in period 1, PDI, must be subtracted from adjusted net nominal AI: earnings, Y1 . .' _ t .t 1 E1 - [(1-t1)(rr+Kl)BO-(1-tl)Dll+(1-t1)(V1)(K1)(1 - ETI)INO -(1-tl)(mp) MO-t1(mp)(CLO-CAO+INO)-thDO-FDq . _ - _ _ 1 K1(“P1) "1(K1)(1 2T;)IN0+(rr*K1)Mo 1+7 Thai Jterm on the R.H.S. is historical-dollar accounting earnings available to common stockholders, E1. 80 that: O _ a U l,' U ~U : 1 a . . “I — “Inr‘l(‘)‘/1)""1(r‘1M1 - 2Tl’l”e+(rr+K1)Mo Substituting back for the 2nd term R.H.S.: . f“ lea}? i_ K1(DP1) -DR1 i‘ r—llHKlloHl - 2: sh) —o 1 J); h—o -1‘ wind (mg-1 ’i) Then: / .. . "’0 (ids. - '1 ‘1 a = , _.. <fl 1 . _ s. , _. _ . Ll JRl , iI \(xlI )(1 a. sh) B1_i(IO(1+Kl) I.) E ‘ _ ; 1 i=o<: i L_ O h=o l 3 R 1 . “VIMIM1 - 2T?)1No+(rr+Kl)Mo Thus we have formulated a model of true after-tax net nominal earnings, or TANNE. The economic significance of each of the terms is: El: Represents the increase in TANNE due to historical- dollar accounting earnings. ”'43 13:51 I" i - -DR " —— K I 1 - "‘ B -s . I 1 K -I- : 1 5&0 Ii i( l o)( Méb h) 1-1( 0( + 1) 1% 4b Represents the decrease in TANNE due to the under depreciation of gross fixed assets in an inflationary period caused by the difference between historical- dollar and general price-level adjusted depreciation. ‘ , 1 t . . . ,i -/ (K )(1 - s——)IN : Represents the decrease in TANNE due 1 1 2T1 o to inflation caused in.entory holding gains. (rr+K1)MO: Represents the increase in TANNE due to a net- monetary center position in an inflationary periOd. Common Stock Valuation Model eased Upon Historical-Dollar Accountinggnarnings Let us assume that: 1. The firm will generate a constant dividend stream forever. 2. The annual dividend is eXpected to grow at a constant rate of, g, per periou. 3. The cost of equity capital to the firm is defined as the market rate of discount, keo in period 0. 4. k ‘g. 5. DO is the common stock dividend in period 0. 117 Then for the continuous case: 47 John Burr Williams, Theory of Investment Value, Harvard University Press, (1938). Also: David Durand, "Growth Stocks and Petersburg Paradox," Journal of Finance, vol. XII, (Sept., 1957), pp. 348-363. x O‘- l t“ Joe e 11:0 p = O keo-‘g’o D . 0 Let b e —— 0 50 And boEo keo _ P + go 0 But: ke0 3 k0 + wo Or: ko : keo ' W0 0 E k = o o o -o “9 _keot dt 'I‘l'nere D O The dividend payout ratio in period 0. The riskless market rate of discount in period 0. The risk premium on the firm's equity capital in period 0. 50 Let the superscript m denote the stock market. Then: m m b E km = o o + {m eo Pm o 0 And. }(m = km _ wm o eo o 30: 7m km = bIT: O + {In _- Wm o o Pm -o o 0 But. a m ko ko 30: E:o m E: m m b —— + g - w = b —— + I - w o P o o o .m #0 o O I) 0 E0 m 32 m m bo P— _ 0o —m + (g0 - g0) - (wo I WO) 0 I o m m m - - .. w \ E2 = b0 E0 + (20 go) (w 0) Po bo PE b0 03 S 51 Inverting both sides: -m :9 1 be *“o E m m ‘m m m _ 0 b0 Eo + 10((g0 " g0) - (W0 W0)) Multiplying both sides by E0: a 1m P = t’obo‘flo o m 1m m m m bO no + PO((so - so) - (WO - wo)) This can be simplified by substituting DO = bOEO and m m 1m . . . . D0 = bO so, and d1v1d1ng the numerator and the denominator of the R.H.;. by PE. 80 that: LJo P0 = m Do m m ‘E t (go " so) - (W0 - W0) po Thus we have developed a common stock valuation model based upon the historical-dollar dividend per Share, the dividend yield for the market as a whole, the expected dividend growth rate for the firm relative to that of the market, and the risk premium for the firm relative to that of the market as a whole. The economic significance of each of the terms is as follows: D : If the dividend per share increases, then 0 the market price per share increases. t It) <35 g. C 5. The common stock dividend in period 0, Do' is based upon the true after-tax net nominal earnings. Then for the continuous case: 00 O , , g t - keot , . P = D e e dt P = The price per share 0 t=o o o of common stock based 00 I _ _ upon TANNE. z j/fD. t(keo g ) oe dt t=o 55 Integrating the R.H.S. , U _ o keo-go Based upon the premise that the market is efficient the market price per share, PO, will have discounted historical-dollar earnings so that: D . b = —$ Where bO = The dividend payout E 0 ratio based upon Then: TANNE. 56 O Multiplying both sides by keo—gO and dividing both sides by P0: c o o keo PC + go But: ke0 5 k0 + w; k0 = The riskless rate of Or: discount in period 0. . w; = The risk premium on the ko : keo - wo firm's equity capital in Substituting for keo: period 0, based upon TANNE. b.E. . . k0 = :00 + g0 ' wo Let the superscript m denote the stockmarket as a whole: E m 0 O 0 km 2 b m o + g m _ w m o o m ,0 0 p0 But the riskless rate of discount for the firm must be equal to the riskless rate of discount for the market as a whole in period 0. So: 57 Then: I I Im bE o e u E 0 0 o o + g _ w = b m o + g m _ w m P o o o m o o 0 PO I I Subtract g0 - wO from both sides: I I Im b0E0 : b'm Eo + ,‘m _ ' _ w'm _ w.) P o m ‘50 go) i o o o P 0 Divide both sides by b0: I I I I I I I a mu m . m _ _ m _ o _ b0 “0 (go go) (wo we) a" ‘ *T-——a + . o b P b o o o m . nd - Po Multiply 2 term R.H.S. by —E: P o I I Im m Im I Im I F‘ - .. ... :2 g bomso + Po((€o so) (w0 w0)) P ' -m 0 b0 P0 Inverting both sides: I m 33 = bo pc I Tm m Im I Fm I Eo bomEo + P0((go - go) - (wo - wo)) I Multiplying both sides E0: I I b E Pm P ‘7' 1 o : O OI : o o m m m m bomao + Po<<€o — so) - (we - we): 58 Dividing numerator and denominator R.H.S. by PS: P = bo E0 0 1 1m bomEo 'm ' 'm ' m + (so - so) - (wO - “0) P 0 Likewise: p: b1351 II 1 mem . . . . 1 1 +< m- )- m g1 E1 1 1 p1 Dividing both sides of the above equation by P0: P1 I n l 1 P_ : b1 E1 'm 1m P O blhl I I O m + ($1 ’ El) (WI ' W1) P1 bo Eo Multiply R.H.S. by 57—i— 0 Where: bO = Historical-dollar accounting earnings dividend payout ratio. E0 = Historical-dollar accounting earnings. II P1 _ b1 E1 1 boEO —’ " I I po bo Eo blmElm . , , PC + (glm ‘ gi) “ (wlm ' WI) 59 But: m m b E b E o o = o o m _ - m _ Po Pm + (go go) ("0 WO) 0 . m m _ m On the R.H.s. bO E0 - DO SO that: b0E0 0? m m P0 = P5 + (£0 - so) - (wO - WO) 0 b0 3 Substituting for P in the last term R.H.S.: o T 7 Um _ m . —§+(a‘§-ao)- (vac-we) P E P _1 z 1 1 o I I PO bO E0 b m E m . ' . 1 1 +( m-r)-£ (0.0.0.0)AO o 9 o A =0 1 50:0 bl‘o + 1:91:— (0.0.0.0).111 1 + 3f (0.0.0.0)8 (3‘30 0 31“ + 98 (0.0.0.0)51 2 1 f +59 2 (o,o,o.o)A(2D 9 A0 2 1 9 r + :2 2 (0.0.0.0)AE 2 A1 2 1 / f 2 + E D 2 (o.o.o,o)B :9 5 ° 0 2 + %‘1"f‘2‘ (0.0.0.0)83 + . . a bl k -A -B 1 1 1 __ . -1 ko-Ao-BO ’ (k1'A1’51)(ko'Ao“Bo) k _, 1 f(0) *1;- 614 2r _ 1( 9%-- -1)(k -A -B ‘2 k 0 o o) (kl-Al'Bl) * 1 0:0)2 9 r ...—... = (-1 .. ’ - _.— 9A1 )(ko Ao-bo) 1 = - 1 k 0 9f - +1( .. k .. _' '2 ‘ 980 0 A0 :50) (k -i—. —B ) ' K1 1 1 1 2 (k0) fi = _1(k -1 9131 o-Ao-bo) 8 — —1_ R o f(A .A k 0 l’Bo'Bl) A =0 2 El + k1 Al x o 2 A - — + 1 b _ o (k 0 k - l A * ) 2 B _— 1 O o o (X) o k B =0 0 O o 8 =0 1 DIm I 1 + g'm (Dlm ' T rd m '1 + m hen 3 term R.H.S. = P1 PT g1 )g0 ' Dm + m - g1 —% + gm (Do m 2 Dm P o 73 + g) —0 m 0 Po 0 (pm + go) o 'm (8}. + 'm m m g1 )(w “w) pl 0 o 'm ' + (wl 'w) om - 1 _2 m 2 m (Pm + go) D—o m o m + g P o o 65 Thus: 'm 'm 01 'm 01 'm 0 : (T+gl) (T'gl) o P b E P P g _l:._1.+._.- 1 - 1 g+ 1 Po bo E0 Um Dm , o Dm (—9 +g'“) (—9- +gW (—9—+ m) “m o Pm o Pym go r0 0 o I m D 1 ’m m (ffi— + $1 ) (WC-WC) cm a P1 w1 “"1 - m + m + e D U 0 m 2 o m (E5 + £0) (Efi + go) o 0 But: m 111 D0 111 keo z Pm + go 0 Likewise: I m km = 01 + g'm e1 J1 PT 'm m D D Substituting for —%— + gim and —% + g3: P P 1 o ' ' m m ' m P1 _ b1 E1 ke1 (kel) g1 ke1 m 5; i B; + E; _ (km )- (km )2 go + km - (km )2 (wo-wo) eo eo e0 90 I I w -w + 1m 1 + e (k ) 66 m k Multiplying the 5th and 7th term R.H.S. by —§9: keo ' ' m m m ' m m 51 = E1 + E1 _ ke1 _ (Rel) g keogl _ (ke1)(wo-wo) P E .m m 2 o m 2 m 2 o o o Keo (keo) (keo) (keo) km (w.m-w.) + co 1 1 + e (km )2 eo Combining terms: p b. E. km km km ' _1 = _1 + _1 _ e1 _ elgo eogl po bo Eo kzo (k20)2 m m m 'm _ ke1(wo-wo) - keo(w1 -W1) + e m 2 (km) The economic significance of each of these terms is as follows: I b1 3_ 2 If the ratio of the current period TANNE dividend o payout ratio increases relative to the previous period's historical-dollar accounting dividend payout ratio then the relative price per share increases. I E1 E" : If the ratio of TANNE per share to historical- 0 dollar accounting earnings per share increases 3‘ <33 ...; 3' a>5 O k 67 then the relative price per share increases. : If the relative cost of equity capital for the market as a whole increases then the relative price per share decreases. m _km ' elgo eogl m 2 : (keo) This is an interactive term. For a constant eXpected dividend growth rate for the firm, i.e. g1 = g . 0 Then: m m _g' (kel'keo) 1 m 2 (Rec) 50 that if the cost of equity capital for the market as a whole increases the relative price per share decreases, not only by the amount of the increase in m kel' but also by a factor of: Similarily for a constant cost of equity capital for the market as a whole, i.e. m m ke1 = keo' Then: km( - I) — I _ so g0 g1 = _ g0 g1 (km )2 km so 60 m m m ke1(wo‘wo)'keo(w1 68 So that if the eXpected dividend growth rate increases, the relative price per share increases not only by the amount of the increase in the expected rate of dividend growth, but also by a factor of: It should be noted that an increase in the cost of equity capital will have a greater effect on the relative price per share than an increase in the eXpected dividend growth rate because: 1 1 . m (k20)2> (REC) Since keo<1.0. I I m_w1) (k m )2 80 : This is an interactive term. For a constant relative risk premium for the firm to the risk premium for the market as . m 'm ' w . . w -w = w -w a hole, 1 e o o 1 1 Then: (w'm w'>(km ~km > 1 ‘ 1 e1 e0 m 2 (1:80) 69 So that if the cost of equity capital for the market as a whole increases the relative price per share decreases, not only by the amount of the increase in kgl. but also by a factor of: _1____ m 2 (keo) Similarily for a constant cost of equity capital for the market . . m - m as a wnole, i.e. ke1 ~ ke0 Then: kid (”‘3‘“0 >~ > - m 2 e0) (k So that if the risk premium for the firm relative to the risk premium for the market as a whole increases the relative price per share decreases not only by the amount of the in- crease in the risk premium of the firm relative to the risk premium of the market as a whole, but also by a factor of: 70 In order to specify the model, substitute: m Do m _ m — + g - 1! P11: 0 eo o I Dlm fin — * g1 " ke1 PT Im Im D1 'm 01 'm o : ("I—n" + $1 ) (—51 + g1 ) 0 p1 b1 E1 P1 P1 g1 —— z —— + —— - - g + P b E m m o m o o o D D D o m o m 2 ( o m (*5 + go) (“a + go) *5 + g0) P P P o o o I m D 1 'm (T + g1 )(W ’wO) :m : P1 (w1 -w1) - + + e (E: "52 (B: + m) Pm g0 pm go o o I Substituting for E1 from Chapter III: ~d) 1 71 Then: I 3.1.. 2 b1 1 E}. Po 5—0 E0 DR ‘90 :3. i ' “ET—1“ 2’ 1—3L “(110”l ‘ 2 En)" o 1=o i h=o IN M . 1 o 0 ’ V1(K1)(1 ' ET?) E;— * (FrtK1) E; 0"" 0"" 1 'm 1 'm ‘5‘ + g1 ) (—5- + g1 ) . P1 P1 g1 .. .. g + _m m o m Do m Do m 2 Do 1 + so) (—m + so) (—In + P P P o o o I m D . -1- + g m) . . PT 1 (W1"1 - wl) — m (w - w ) + m D . D (—°— + gmf (—0 + gm) Pm 0 Pm o o o r = rr + K1 And: m = r + K P r P 72 Then: =' -K rr p p 80 that: . . - = + - r mp K1 Kp Thus: M M M +(K-K)—2 r 1 E0 p so 1 p 30 Thus we postulate the following: P 1 - T7'* (90+181 O r I I b E BL +32 El 0 O 3 E . 0 i=0 I' i h=o ‘ IN M i __1_ __9 8 - _0 -05 V1(K1)(1 - 2T1) E20 +. 6[mp(EO)J + 7 'm - f 'm W (D .m 01 .m l -- + s (-- + g ) Pm 1 pm 1 -8 1 -8 1 g .8 8 Dm 9 Dm o 10 Dm o m o m 2 0 P5 + 60 (P5 + go) PE .0 J 1 0 j _0 r- u ‘1 m DI om F 1 (T + g1 ) cm 0 p1 W1 - W1 -6 wm-w)-M3 11 Dm o o 12 Dm o m 2 o m (—— + g ) -— + s m o m o P P o o — J » l rDR “if CS- 1 ..(? .——l 2:: [——£ (KIIO)(1‘ :5: Eh)" B1—1(Io(1+K1)-Ii) B (kl-RP)E—‘: 73 b nd term R.H.S. multiply by Si 1 In the 2 b1 {3 b1 D1 =. ( )( ) 1 b0 1 b1 b0 (3 Then let: I I . b b [?1 =/§;(Bl) where —l-is a scaling constant. 1 1 In the at“ term k.H.S. In order to evaluate the proxy for the underdeprecia- tion of real fixed assets when historical—dollar accounting and general price-level accounting depreciation are com- pared, we have employed a Lagrangian interpolation tech— nique to estimate the lagged coefficients for this term.“9 In: DR "00 cs 1 E_l.§E: I—l K110 (1- E3 Eh) - Bl_i(10(1+K1)—Ii) 0 i=0 i h=o 1 Let 3,-1 = (1- 52% sh) - Bl_i(IO(1+K1)—Ii) 49 S. Almon, "The Distributional Lag Between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures,“ Econometrica, (Jan. 1965), pp. 178-196. 7:: Then: DR —oo 1 1 — E ii: [TK1I0)(1- :§:'Bh)- Bl_i(Io(1+Kl)-Iifl _ 0 =0 h 0 ~00 Z 5/ . C31 0R1 i=0 -1 I:— [Kllo] E;— Assuming 5 i = O: for all i< -10 Construct 2nd Degree pagrangian interpolation polynomials: g (-igj) Where: i = O, 000. -10 Such that: 5’-1 =’Gg fl (—i.1) +/?u fl (-1,2) Then: __ A) .- DR1 cs. 10 E /93 ‘fl (- -i, 1) 0 i= 0 1. C81 DR +3 :6 (-1. 2)]l:(_1c>)(K11)('E_’1‘) O The R. H. S. can be rewritten: ~10 DRl 83 120 :6 (- -1, Inf—Q— 11 )(x110)(E——0 ) -10 S DR +(3u 2:: fl ( i 2) (f:$)(KIIO)(E—$) i=0 0 75 Let: 3;; fl ( 1> Z = -i. ———’ K I -—- 1 i=0 Ii 1 0 E0 and -10 . ‘8. 0R 2 = Z (-i.2>(—l—) K 1 ) _1: 2 i=0 g 1.1 ( 1 0 (E0 ’ 21 and 22 are the variables which are entered into the regression equation. The fl (-i,j) are constructed 50 according to formula in Almon, and the other elements in 21 and 22 are available from our data sources. In the 8th term R.H.5., if we assume homogeneity of investor expectations about KP, the previously anticipated future rate of inflation, then in cross section analysis Kl-K will be a constant. P Then let: B7 = 37(K1-Kp) th In the 9th, 10th, 11th 12th and 13 terms. D2 m D1m 'm _E + go and "5’ + g1 will be constants in cross section P P o 1 analysis. Then let 2 0"“ 0' (7:— + . u- = P m 8 8 1 g1 ) m _9. m + m p0 g0) 01"" (— 9 i 1 ) Di (.9. m + m 2 6). p0 g0) 10 -3 10 1 Dm <-9 + m m Po go) b'm f2' 6’ 1 11 = m + .m 11 P1 81 ) Dm (.2 I}; + g2)?- [3 O 12 ‘01 2 Dm (—°+ m m p0 go) 76 H‘ u— ._‘. 77 Then: F 1 p1 ° b1 E1 -10 DR1 I -p— =8 +01 b—o +82 E— J33 Z 2! <-1.1)(-f——:110)(——> O 0 EO _ J -10 DR #3.. Z ¢(-1.2)(-::—iix)(1<110)(§—i) i=0 0 IN M . M J35 vlmlm - ——1—>(E—09) +36 ‘p5 1 ”o 1 ' As a result of these criteria 240 firms were used in the 1965 regressions, while 21h firms were used in the 1972 tests. PROCEEUURE The regression equation to be estimated is: r ' ~10 , “ b E _ C5. Us 1 _ ' 1 :7 __1; f) ‘7-1 _. l ~ 1 .3" -[}o+'/))1'b_ +/)2 s “”3 .44 fl(1'1HI. )(KIIOME ) O O 0 1‘0 1 O r 8 l.:_'3 L101 0K1 " u[ :4 g ('lv2)(l )(K110)(E ) 1‘0 1 C IN M M- . 1 o - o ' o 1 -‘[{5{V1(K1)(1 - 5T1”)?- BC) mp(EO) +/)7 E; _/)51 0 J. O O m 0 Um Q -09[gOJ+/)10’L51 -/))11 [W0 - WO‘]+/212[wl - W1 + 8 Since the net—monetary debtor leverage variables M ) and E2 are highly colinear, we were forced to o :11]: 0 E: p( O drOp one of these two variables in order to estimate 82 the regressions. It was decided to retain ap -19 V” ”“1 i __.— =: _—| ) I J .. ‘ ‘- P ')o +’/1[QIT /i: + j) ‘: fl ( lol)il. )(h110)\r II 0 OJ o 1—0 1 o 1 -10 C. J“ 1 _., Ui‘ , l +/;1 :1: fl (‘1:4)(ff")(nllo)(E—“) i=0 1 o ' m ’ .- M / 1 O [2 " O / . + . - H—— <—- +1) :- + ' /{5 llUllm1 2T1 h mp(s ) I)9 go o o /." '6 r ' m ,/h 'm ' +5310 g1 +1fill wo - w +/)12 w1 — w1 + e PO: krice per share of common stock for the previous year. P1: Brice per share of common stock for the current year. b x The dividend payout ratio for the previous year, 1) based upon historical-dollar accounting bO = no. L‘O b1: The dividend payout ratio for the current year, “1 based upon historical—dollar accounting b1 = E—° 1 E z The historical-dollar accounting earnings in the previous year. at: El: The historical-dollar accounting earnings in the current year. m : The embedded money rate of interest. K1: The actual inflation rate in the current period. I : The C.P.I. value in the previous period. 0 . , . .tn . 1.: The C.r.I. value in the 1 period. 1 obi: The capital spending in the l periOd. 0R1: The depreciation rate in the current period, based upon historical-dbllar accounting. V1: A dummy variable such that V1 0 if sIEO V1 1 if FIFO T1: Inventory turnover rate. INC: The dollar amount of inventories for the previous period. MO: Net monetary debtor position for the previous period. go: The expected dividend growth rate as perceived during the previous year. g1: The eXpected dividend growth rate as perceived during the current year. wE—w : The relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole as perceived during the previous year, where: w: represents the risk of the market and wO represents the risk of the individual firm. The relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole as perceived during the current year. 05 RESULTS UP THE dTbbY The most significant regression results are reported in Table l. The Hz values, while low, are not unusually low for cross section analysis. The IUll regression moeel, Eq. VI. has an kg = .sto for 1905 and an a2 = .5950 for 1972. In 1905 Lq. I, wnicn represents the relationship between the relative stocx prices and the relative historical-dollar accountinr dividend payout ratios plus the relative nintariCal~ddllar accounting earnings, has an H2 = .1930. sq. VI, which is the full model, has an R = .3u00. Thus the relative dividend payout ratios plus relative historical-dollar accounting earnings are reSponsible for 57 percent of the total explained variance in relative stock prices during 1905. In 1972 hi. I has an kg = .1135, as compared to Eq. VI which has an H2 = .2950, was responsible for only 30 percent of the total explained variance in relative stock prices that year. From a different point of view the additional explanatory variables of sq. VI, as compared to Eq. I. were responsible for only “3 percent of the explained variance in relative stock prices during 1965, while in a period of relatively high inflation, 1972, these additional variables were reSponsible for 62 percent of the eXplained variance in relative stock prices. .. On '. s. ‘ . .J . . .. ,. .. . P! -o . .. v ,. . ‘ -| ... .. 1 ' ‘4 'v ' . n ‘ I. ’ 1. .‘ - . v c . nu . “. 1 4| ‘. ’ I .- . . ‘ I .. c .1 z, - . ‘ I ,. c . . a r. . . ‘ I . 4 u‘ " o ,. ‘11 , . ,- v n. .. . . ..J ..... n .‘- ; .1 '1‘ .0 j . .-1 . ‘. 3. .. «I "~ :1. Y - .ll 1 l « .:| -. r ’1 -# o ...l :"I A ' I; I I - v 4 U ‘ ' v or. n’ I . .. V ? 4 ul :) . . A 3 . .4 ’ t ' ) ' I . . {’1 ‘ . '1 a (J ,_ ,. . . | .4 I I) (V l) 4': w .a .1 i) . . | .4 I ‘1. {I I, .c ’I O 0‘ I!) .4, A ' 1 \ ‘ --~ ... \ ' .‘ . a . . ‘ . . ' . . . x' y 5 . . .. Q C : ‘ .’ . . _ . . . I 4 o . I .. . v v’ ‘ ‘ - . .o t .4 . 4 v' .3 . - ' -- f ' ? ‘ -4 7 I 5 ‘ ' .o - . . . . . . . . 4 ’ ~~4 ' .l o .. .4 .. o .. . l I s I n 1 l -' l ‘ < l ' . i . l- , . . . j a f .4 .. _0 .. .‘ . ‘ r ‘, I r‘ l . . . . . . . . . . 1 l I v I r | r. l .. I 1 . x -a r r ' v,- '. :. ' 1 l . r , y 1 r ? .a ‘ u -) ‘1 ', . ‘ _, . .' .s v . . . 1 .. . Q ' ,. . . . . . . . . . . . . . .- 1 V .4 I . . .. : v. I: . ,. 1.) I .4 ' . " 1 y ‘. 1: '. 5 #1 u {1 1 I I. . K‘ ‘ .4 7c (,. ’V f I» ‘ x . a . - J \1 '- ‘ ‘ 3 ' -4 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I l P I . 1 I .4 .. I A J I I , I I v f 11 '1 , ( ’ ) ’ I: .d g) .a ' I) ‘ Ir I) ' I) .1 ' " ‘x -‘ ' J a 3 I I) ' I) .‘ ‘ ( “ I I) .. .o .. U ‘ v r ' : ‘ ’\ 1‘“. .4 '. 1 D .4 t "\ . . . . . . ~ . o n o . o . . J l: J I "‘ I ‘\ l' " U '1 ' l) l) ‘l\ '- -f\ .l -l '-J '1 1‘ x, .4 r“ J .: ' .—o r) n I": I I" J ‘ I) 1; f l ( l1 - p .- y -) I) t y .4 ( .a f ’1 .0 .0 7 ’ H .4 ) V) l‘ .4 l1 ' . . . . . . . o . . . . . . . ,.. ‘ v. ‘ I Q ,4 Q "\ I .l l I I l l 1 I l l I .z . . « u ') H Y I) l l) (' 7 'V I" 1‘ u-4 '7‘) I: P nt ’ I "\ ' 'I f “3 v0 ’1 .4 () ,‘ , r :1 .1 H 1' ‘7. I"\ f) ) -'\ :\) \I\ :‘\ ’l H I t 'l ‘1‘ .4 “J 'I "\ .I 7 ‘ J .4 . . . . . . . - - . . . . . (‘1 I .1 'l I v-4 - I .4 l - | l O r) V\ ,1 \l\ n: It\ a) If\ f‘ 0 f l“) {-2 L') f‘- D n r) 1 t) (Y 1% (7 (7\ r‘ .c .d .4 v4 .4 F4 .—4 pa ii .’ :4 ... :- fj‘ rj‘ (II (I) (I) U‘ ..J .‘ :3 .: ( v .1 87 Analysis of the Coefficients of the Individual Variables The constant term,/30, is consistently negative in the 1965 regressions and is statistically significant at the 5 percent level in only one of the six regressions. While in the 1972 regressions the constant term is consistently positive and significant at the 5 percent level in three of the six regressions. I 6?1. the coefficient of the relative historical-dollar D/E. accountin aiout ratio 1 l is consistentl ne ative g P J : 5375;: y g for both years. In 1905 it is significant at the 5 percent level in only two of the six regressions, while in 1972 it is significant in all six regressions. /32, the coefficient of the relative historical-dollar . . E1. .. accounting earnings, 5—, is pOSitive and Significant at o the 5 percent level in both years for all regressions. Linear combinations of (93 and Z2; generate the g{_i's, the proxy variables for the difference between historical- dollar accounting and general price-level adjusted accounting depreciation, Thus, :E:.¢ (“1:1)(Tf—)(KIIO)(E——) and i=0 1 O -10 C31 DRl 2 fl (‘192)('I'_)(K110)(E_')o i=0 1 0 must be treated as a joint addition to the regression. 88 The hypothesis that they are jointly equal to zero was investigated, because if we are unable to reject the hypothesis that /?3 =/?L = 0 then we cannot reject the hypothesis that 5/-i = O for i = O,..., 10. Since the 1965 test statistic falls in the rejection region there is sufficient evidence to indicate that the joint addition of the proxies for the difference between historical-dollar accounting and general price-level adjusted depreciation contribute significantly, at the 5 percent level, to the regressions. Since the 1972 test statistic does not fall in the rejection region there is no evidence to indicate that the joint addition of the proxies for the difference between historical-dollar accounting and general price-level adjusted depreciation contribute significantly. at the 5 percent level, to the regressions. Table 2 ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE Test of the hypothesis that,[?3 = [94 = O for 1965 Sum of Degrees of Mean F Squares Freedom Squares Total (Restricted) 26.766168 232 .123992 Regression (Unrestricted) 26.019979 230 .116609 Error 1.946189 2 .973095 6.344935 F 04 2.230 y3' 09 TABLE 3 ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE Test of the hypothesis that /33 = A?“ = O for 1972 Sum of Degrees of Mean F squares Freedom Squares Total A (Restricted) 10.051306 200 .0u0793 Regression ' (Unrestricted) 9,9061U1 209 .040952 Error .005245 2 .032023 .000410 F2,2ou ‘ 3'0“ /G;, the coefficient of the proxy for inventory IN gains, V1(K1)(1 — —i~)———, is consistently positive and 2T1 E0 significant at the 5 percent level in all of the 1905 regressions. While in 1972 the coefficient is negative and significant at the 5 percent level for all regressions. [26’ the coefficient of the proxy for net-monetary M debtor leveraging of earnings, mp(E9), is negative in o 1965 and not significant at the 5 percent level. While, in 1972, it is negative but significant at the 5 percent level. [2;, the coefficient of the proxy for the previous year's expectations about the future dividend growth rate, go, has mixed signs and lacks significance at the 5 percent level in all of the 1965 regressions. In 1972 the coefficient is consistently positive, but it is only 90 significant at the 5 percent level in one of the six regressions. (9io, the coefficient of the proxy for the current year's expectations about the future dividend growth rate, gi, has mixed signs and lacks significance at the 5 percent level in the 1905 regressions. While in 1972 it is consistently negative and it also lacks significance at the 5 percent level. These data bear out the previously expressed concern about these overlapping moving averages. Since the estimated coefficients of the proxies, go and gi, for the expected future dividend growth rate are not significant at the 5 percent level, the hypothesis that these coefficients are jointly equal to zero was investigated. The results of these tests are tabulated in Tables 9 and 5. Both the 1965 and 1972 test statistics do not fall in the rejection region, thus there is no evidence to indicate that the joint addition of go and . g1 contribute significantly, at the 5 percent level, to the regressions. 91 TABLE u ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE I I Test of the hypothesis that [39 = (310 = O for 1965 Sum of Degrees of Mean F Squares Freedom Squares Total . . (Restricted) 29.050193 236 .125070 Regression (Unrestricted) 29.507000 23h .120357 Error .090593 2 .045297 .350900 2? 1 F2'23u 3.0+ TABLE 5 ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE I 0 Test of the hypothesis that,/?9 = (910 = O for 1972 Sum of Degrees of Mean F Squares Freedom Squares Total (Restricted) 11.301119 210 .059196 Regression (Unrestricted) 11.336787 200 .054504 Error .044332 2 .022106 .900000 F2,205 ‘ 3'0“ fl3£1, the coefficient of the proxy for the previous year's relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole, w? - wo, is consistently negative and significant at the 5 percent level in all of the 1965 regressions. In the 1972 regressions it was consistently negative, but without significance at the 5 percent level. 92 [312' the coefficient of the proxy for the current year's relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole, w; - wi, is consistently positive and not significant at the 5 percent level in both the 1905 and 1972 regressions. Since the estimated coefficients of the proxies, m '3 ' w - w and w ‘- w o o 1 1' are of mixed significance the hypo- thesis that these coefficients are jointly equal to zero was investigated. The results of these tests are tabulated in Tables 6 and 7 . Both the 1905 and 1972 test statistics fall in the rejection region. Thus there is sufficient evidence to indicate that the joint addition of w: — WC and wlm- w1 contribute significantly. at the 5 percent level, to the regressions. TAbLE 0 ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE I I Test of the hypothesis/211 =16?12 = O for 1905 Sum of Degrees of Mean F Sguares Freedom squares Total . (Restricted) 29.507000 234 .120357 Regression (Unrestricted) 20.700100 232 .123992 Error .001432 2 .u00710 3.231709 F2'232'— 3.0M 93 TABLE 7 ANALYSIS OF VARIANCE I I Test of the hypothesis /?11 ==K312 = o for 1972 Sum of Degrees of Mean F dguares Freedom Sguares Total (Restricted) 11.330707 200 .05450u Regression . (Unrestricted) 10.051300 200 .0U0793 Error 1.255401 2 .042701 13.171902 a 'y r) 1‘2,206 1'0“ INTERPRETATION OF THE RESULTS The constant term,/3;, is without consistent signifi- cance and thus does not lend itself to interpretation. The relative Dividend Payout Ratio The coefficient of the relative dividend payout ratio, [;£, is consistently negative. but is significant at the 5 percent level in only one third of the regressions in the relatively low inflation year 1905. While in the high inflation year 1972 it is consistently negative and significant at the 5 percent level. These results indicate that an increase in the relative dividend payout ratio will cause a decrease in the price per share of a firm's common stock, ceteris paribus. Thus investors act as if they believe that when a firm retains a lower percentage of its earnings relative to the previous year's retention rate that the 9“ price per share of its common stock will decrease relative to the previous year’s share price, because the future earnings potential has been reduced by the relatively lower retention rate. A second interpretation which is consistent with these results is that for a given total return on a share of common stock, dividends plus price appreciation, if a firm increases its dividend relative to the previous year's dividend then the price per share does not have to increase relative to the previous year's share price in order to maintain the given total return. It should be noted from Table 1, that in the 1905 regressions where the coefficient is statistically significant the value of the coefficient is approximately one-half the value of the 1972 coefficient. This indicates that in a period of relatively high inflation, ceteris paribus, a unit change in the earnings retention rate will cause almost twice the change in relative prices as com- pared to a unit change during periods of relatively low inflation. Further, if a firm wants to increase the relative price per share it should increase its retention rate, i.e. reduce its current dividend payout ratio, and this is even more important in a period of relatively high inflation. That firms may have employed this strategy appears to be borne out by the fact that the 95 mean value of the 1972 relative dividend Dl/Do is only 91.5 percent of the mean value of the 1905 relative dividend ratio. The Relative Historical-Dollar Accounting Earnings The coefficient of relative historical—dollar earnings, [92, is consistently positive and statistically significant in both years indicating that investors appear to like a relative increase in earnings per share. It should be noted from Table 1 that in the period of relatively high inflation, 1972, the values of the coefficient are approximately one-half those found in the period of a relatively low inflation, 1905. Thus in a period of relatively high inflation, ceteris paribus. investors appear to discount relative increases in historical-dollar earnings by approximately 50 percent, as compared to relative earnings in a period of low inflation. This may be an indication that investors may perceive a "quality of earnings" problem in relative historical-dollar accounting earnings in a period of relatively high inflation. The Difference Between Historical~Dollar and General- Price Level Adjusted Depreciation The coefficients of the Lagrangian polynomial proxies for the difference between historical-dollar accounting and general price-level adjusted depreciation,(3/_i, which are generated by linear combinations of /93 and/(fa, are significant at the 5 percent level in the 1905 90 regression. and not significant in the 1972 regression. In evaluating the individual values of the lagged coefficients developed by means of the Lagrangian poly- nomial it was found that the proxies for the most recent four years were all positive and significant at the 5 percent level in the 1905 regressions. In the 1972 regression, the coefficients of the proxies for the most recent three years were positive and significant at the 5 percent level. and in addition the coefficient of the most distant lagged proxy was negative and significant. All other coefficients were not significant at the 5 percent level in either year. These results are at variance with those predicted in the full model. except for the most distant lagged year of the 1972 regressions. This anomaly may be caused by our inability to specify the replacement variable Bh' the percentage of this period's capital Spending that is replaced h periods later. Thus, the chosen proxy repre- sents general price-level adjusted capital spending with no provision for the replacement or the retirement of fixed assets. In this more restricted context the signs of the significant coefficients of the lagged proxies have economic meaning. In a period of relatively low inflation, 1965, investors looked favorably upon capital spending during the most recent four years. While in a period of relatively higher rate of inflation, 1972, 97 investors only looked with favor on the most recent three year's capital Spending, while capital spending in the 10th previous year was looked upon as being deleterious to stock prices. The Inventory Holding Gain The coefficient of the inventory holding gain proxy, /?5, is consistently significant at the 5 percent level for both 1905 and 1972. We therefore would like to investigate the following hypotheses: Hypothesis I: In periods of continuing inflationary expectations the sign of the coeff- icient should be significant and negative, and in periods when there are no expectations of continuing inflation the sign should not be significant or negative. Hypothesis II: In periods when there are no expect- ations of continuing inflation and firms eXperience inventory holding gains the coefficient should be significant and positive. In 1905 the sign of the coefficient is consistently positive indicating that, in that year of relatively low inflation, investors looked favorably upon such gains. Using mean values of the 1905 data series, the average 90 proxied holding gain represented only 5.9 percent of the increase in earnings for that year. Also, 1905 was the final year in a seven year period of relative price stability, when the inflation rate averaged less that 1.3 percent per year so that firms could look forward to replacing inventories at approximately the same cost. Thus investors might well perceive such holding gains as enhancing the relative price per share of a firm's common stock in a period of price stability. In 1972 the sign of the coefficient is consistently negative, indicating that, in that year of relatively high inflation, investors looked with disfavor upon such gains. Using mean values of the 1972 data series, the average holding gain proxy represented 19.2 percent of the increase in earnings for the year. 1972 was the final year in a seven year period of relatively high inflation when the average annual rate of inflation exceeded 4.1 percent. Investors recognizing that inventory holding gains represented almost one-fifth of the increase in earnings for the year, and if their expectations were for an increasing rate of inflation this could mean inventory replacement at substantially higher costs leading to uncertainty about future earnings. The coefficients for 1905 and 1972 regressions are consistent with hypothesis I, and the coefficient for the 1965 regression is consistent with hypothesis II. 99 The uncertainty about the true worth of inventory holding gains in a period of relatively high inflation may cause investors to perceive such gains as having a deletarious effect upon the relative price per share. The Net-Monetary Debtor Leverage The coefficient of the net-monetary debtor leverage proxy,/?6, was negative in both years and significant at the 5 percent level only in 1972. The coefficient's lack of significance in 1905 indicates that investors tended to ignore a firm's net-monetary debtor leverage position in valuing its common stock. That investors appear to have ignored a firm's net-monetary debtor leverage position may be attributable to two facts: in 1905 the mean value of the net-monetary debtor position proxy per dollar of earnings was only $1.31 and the mean value of the embedded cost of net-monetary debt was only 3.90 percent that year, for a mean total cost of servicing net-monetary debt of $.O50 per dollar of current earnings. In a period of relatively high inflation, such as 1972, the model and previous studies indicate that a net-monetary debtor leverage position should enhance the value of a firm's common stock. However, the results of these regressions indicate that investors appear to dis- count the value of a highly leveraged firm's common stock even in a period of relatively high inflation. This 100 apparant anomaly may be explained by two facts: in 1972 the mean net—monetary debtor position per dollar of earn- ings was over three times that of 1905 at $4.20 and the mean embedded cost of net-monetary debt had increased fifty-five percent to 0.15 percent for a mean total cost of servicing net-monetary debt of $.259 per dollar of current earnings. The fact that the degree of net-monetary debt leveraging had increased over three times while the embedded cost of net-monetary debt had increased by one- half resulting in over a four-fold increase in the cost of servicing net—monetary debt may have overcome the beneficial effects of a net-monetary debtor position in a period of relatively high inflation. The Expected Dividend Growth Rates The coefficients of the expected dividend growth I I rate proxies, (29 and K? 10 are of mixed signs and lack consistent statistical significance in both 1905 and 1972. The joint addition of these two variables likewise does not contribute significantly to the regression. The Relative Risk Premium The coefficients of the relative risk premium proxies, I I /?.11 and/(312 are individually of the predicted sign in both 1905 and 1972, but only the 1905 coefficients for the previous year's relative risk premium are significant at the 5 percent level. However, the joint addition of the relative risk premium proxies are significant at the 101 5 percent level in both 1905 and in 1972. These results indicate that proxies based upon the Value Line Investment Survey risk-rankings when incorporated in the valuation model deveIOped in this research perform as predicted. The average value of the risk premium proxies in 1905 were close to the risk premium for the market as a whole, which is 3.0. The mean value for the previous year's risk premium proxy was 2.05 decreasing slightly to 2.74 for the current year's risk premium proxy in 1905. In 1972 the mean values of the previous year and the current year risk premium proxies are identical at 2.24 indicating a further decrease in the risk level for the firms studied in this research. This decrease in risk may be attributable to Value Line's more generous use of the higher "safety" classifi- cations in 1972 as compared to its 1905 rankings, or to an inaccurate perception of risk in a period of relatively high inflation. 102 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS Investors appear to have learned that in an inflat- ionary period a relatively high dividend payout ratio, or a relatively low earnings retention rate, reduces future earnings potential. This is reflected, of course, in relatively lower prices per snare for a given level of dividends. This finding appears to be at variance with 51 the works of frofessors Gordon and Arditti. However, it should be pointed out that their empirical studies covered periOds of relative price stability and were based upon historical—dollar accounting data. Investors have detected the inventory profit illusion. Thus FIFU-caused inventory holding gains in a period of relatively high inflation do not help the relative price per share. Investors appear to discount an increase in relative historical-dollar accounting earnings in a period of high inflation by approximately 50 percent as compared to the same increase in relative historical—dollar accounting earnings in a period of low inflation. Thus investors appear to perceive a "quality of earnings" problem in 51 Myron J. Gordon, "Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices," The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 41, no. 2, (May. 1959). pp. 99-105. Fred D. Arditti. "Risk and the Required Rate of Return on Equity," The Journal of Finance, vol. 22, (March, 1907), pp. 19-36. 103 relative historical-dollar accounting earnings during an inflationary period. Investors were not sensitive to a firm's net-monetary debtor leverage position in a period of price stability. This finding is in accord with previous studies. Also, previous studies indicate that a net-monetary debtor position should enhance relative common stock prices in a periOd of relatively high inflation. The results of this study indicate just the Opposite effect - that investors look with disfavor upon a net-monetary debtor position. These results may be due to investor fears that the debt burden is excessive in view of the higher costs of servic- ing that debt and the increased uncertainties about the "quality" and variability of future earningso By incor- porating the cost of servicing a net-monetary debtor pos- ition in this study we have included not only the benefits, but also the costs attributable to such a position. Thus these results may not be at variance with previous studies, but represent an extension of Professors Alchian, Kessel and others. Investors appear to be indifferent to the under- depreciation of fixed assets caused by the use of historical-dollar accounting in comparison to general price-level adjusted accounting. This may be attributable to our inability to Specify the replacement variable in 104 the model, or it may indicate that investors are insens- itive to the more distant lagged capital spending in periods of relatively high inflation. The study failed to get a clear reading on both expected dividend growth rates and the effect of risk upon stock valuation. APPENDIX APPENDIX DEFINITION OF VARIABLES A. Source: VALUE LINE INVESTMENT SURVEY, "Summary of Advices and Index". P The average of weekly closing prices for December of the current year. The relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole as perceived in the second week of the December prior to the current year. Risk was proxied using VALUE LINE'S five risk class estimates. The firm was assigned a rating of 1 - 5, with risk classification 1 representing the least risky classification. The market as a whole was assigned the median risk classification 3. wg—w : The relative risk of the firm to that of the market as a whole as perceived in the second week of the December prior to the previous year. Risk was proxied using VALUE LINE'S five risk class estimates. The firm was assigned a rating of 1 - 5, with risk classification 1 105 100 representing the least risky classification. The market as a whole was assigned the median risk classification 3. Source: Standard and Poor's Annual Primary Industrial File, COMPUSTAT tape. (Data Item shall be referred to as DI) The historical-dollar accounting earnings in the II] previous year. 00 = Available for Common (DI 20) D1: The common stock dividend per share (DI 20) bl: The dividend payout ratio for the current year. 01 = DI Available for common (DI 20) Common shares outstanding (DI 25) mp: The embedded money rate of interest. Fixed charges (DI 15) = + Preferred dividends (D1 19; p Long term debt (DI 97— + Debt in current liabilities (DI 34) Preferred at redemption value (DI 50) CS.: The capital expenditures (DI 30) 0R1: The depreciation rate in the current period. = Depreciation and amortization (D1 14) UR1 Gross plant and equipment (D1 7) V A dummy variable such that V1 = 0 if LIEU 13 V1 1 if FIFO V1 z Inventory valuation method (U1 59) 107 T1: Inventory turnover rate. _ Cost of goods sold (DI 41) T1 fl Inventories TDI 3) INO: Inventories (DI 3) MO: The net-monetary debtor position for the previous period. MO = Current liabilities (DI 5) + Long term debt (DI 9) + Preferred stock at redemption value (DI 5o) - (Current assets (DI 4) - Inventories (DI 3)) g1: The eXpected dividend growth rate as perceived during the current year I (D ‘31 Dt = Dividends per share (DI 20) Ii: The C.P.I. value for the current period. 10: The C.P.I. value for the previous period. K1: The inflation rate for the current period. THE BI BLI OGRAPHY THE BIBLIOGRAPHY Alchian, Armen, and Kessel, Reuben. "The Meaning and Validity of Inflation — Induced Lag of Real Wages behind Prices.” American Economic Review, vol. 50 (March, 1900), pp. 43-00. Alchian, Armen, and Kessel, Reuben. "The Redistribution of Wealth Through Inflation." Sciencg, vol. 130 (September 4, 1959): Pp- 535-539. Almon, S. ”The distributional Lag Between Capital ApprOpriations and Expenditures." Econometrica, (January, 1905), pp. 170-190. Arditti. Fred D. “Risk and the Required Rate of Return on Equity.“ The Journal of Finance, vol. 22 (March, 1907)! pp- 139-36- Bach, G.L., and Ando, A. "The Redistributional Effects of Inflation." Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 37, (February, 1957), pp. 1-13. Bach, G.L., and Stephenson, James B. "Inflation and the Redistribution of Wealth." The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. LVI (February, 1974), pp. 1-13. Bresciani~Turroni, Economics of Inflation, London: MacMillan Co., 1937, pp. 253,298. Broussalian, V.A. "Unanticipated Inflation: A Test of the Debtor—Creditor Hypothesis." Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of California, Los Angeles, 1901. De Alessi, Louis. "The Redistribution of Wealth by Inflation: An Empirical Test With U.K. data." Southern Economic Review, vol. 3 (October, 1903), pp. 113-127. 100 109 De Alessi, Louis. "Do Businesses Gain From Inflation." Journal of Business, vol. 37 (April, 1969), pp. 159-166. Durand, David. "Growth Stocks and Petersburg Paradox." Journal of Finance, vol. XII (September, 1957), Felix, D.E. "Profit Inflation and Industrial Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 70 (August, 1956). PP: uni—“6?. Fisher, 1. The Purchasing Power of Money. New York: MacMillan Co., 1920, pp. 58¥73, 190-191, Gordon, Myron J. "Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices.“ The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 41, no. 2. (May. 1959). pp- 99-105. Graham, F.D. Exchange Prices and Production in Hyper- Inflation: Germany 1920-2}. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1930, pp. 74, 177. Hamilton, E.J. "Prices as a Factor in Business Growth." Journal of Economic History, vol. XII (Fall, 1962), pp' 325’ Bug- Kessel, Reuban. "Inflation Caused Wealth Redistribution: A Test of a Hypothesis." American Economic Review, vol. 66 (March, 1956), pp. 128-191. Keynes, J.M. Tract on Monetary Reform. London: MacMillan Co., 1923, pp. 18—19. Prichard, Woodward 0. "Inflation, Expectations and Wealth Redistribution.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan, 1970. "Reporting the Effect of Price Level Changes." Accounting Research Study #6, American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, New York, 1963, p. 16. Rosenfeld, Paul, "Accounting For Inflation: A Field Test." Journal of Accountancy, (June, 1969), pp. U5-50. Terborgh, George. Essays in Inflation. Washington, Machinery and Allied Products Institute, 1971, pp. 53—5“. 110 Thiel, H. Applied Economic Forcasting. Chicago: Rand-McNally, 1966, pp. U7-“9. Williams, John Burr. Theory of Investment Value. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1938. MITIWWHSIIWW ii("WIVEIWIIHTIWIILHWS 3 1293 030821825