’9'" ’U‘V‘vv" v N ‘ .b- L. All l.‘\,‘..;u . 9"‘V‘ ‘\~f\ not“. '..I* A y y¢ nuau rhly . bu.- !\! T r..\ J. ‘ t «‘1 {ECE“‘ r15 0‘. "twmw' "'.. ‘ F.“ ‘ ~~‘_ '4‘. h18 D'P! ‘ ~‘. 5 r" ‘I ‘ \ - hfi‘ \ s,“ . H h ‘ “‘ NU 5‘1 u "'GiA» "’ \J ”-2., .‘i'. " ALI ; ‘ ““h «S Cr‘e ' ‘ ABSTRACT THE INCOME REDISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF TAXES AND PUBLIC EXPENDITURES IN THAILAND: AN INTERTEMPORAL STUDY BY Medhi Krongkaew A recent rise in interest in the economics of income distribution has prompted much research on income distribu- tion in both developed and underdeveloped countries. This study, which is one among many, is concerned with the sta- tistical estimation of the income redistributional impact of taxes and public expenditures in Thailand in, and between 1963 and 1969. Knowledge of this so-called "fiscal incidence" is important in evaluating and recommending government poli- cies regarding income redistributional issues in Thailand. The study begins with the estimation of money income distribution in 1963 and 1969 using the results of the 1962- 1963 household expenditure survey and the 1968-1969 socio- economic survey as the main sources of data. The money in- come concept is then adjusted for underreported income, im- puted rents, income in kind, net corporate savings and in- direct taxes. The new, more comprehensive income concept is called "adjusted income," and both income concepts are used in computing the effective rates of taxes and expenditures of .1 rare fiscal 5'; ........ms at e c; :;;;::em which w; resent: tax ar. ‘xzfi a?" Edi " ifi wily ure ((4.- . fiwv-‘van .....__:-_ as ar .. . :.:;;‘-.‘._\ $ ‘ ' ~ "-‘vlcn 3.0, tnl b \"\~ ‘ '-..~ r, ~ I “in nyet b3 L2)— " ‘4‘ \: ‘\..'_ | "f; t \ .‘L 85 Bra“! ' QVKG‘ "& "°'~6d i. lam“ ”~U,. . is I» Ni, V "\ .st A var‘ ‘ kl“? - “ U‘la Midi» ‘L n KICFM \ ‘ e b’r ‘ I ‘u n h | v Cr 4‘. ‘ ‘& th‘ {‘q L‘ Medhi Krongkaew the entire fiscal system. These money and adjusted income distributions are called the "pre-fisc" income distribution, the pattern which would result if the government replaced the present tax and expenditure program with a proportional tax and expenditure program. The tax incidence is then in— terpreted as a reduction from, and the expenditure incidence an addition to, this pre-fisc income. The estimation of tax incidence by income classes in 1963 and 1969 is carried out conventionally, that is, first certain shifting assumptions are decided upon, and, second, the absolute tax burdens are allocated to different income brackets according to certain allocation criteria. On the expenditure side, the accounting approach, where total expendi— ture benefits are assumed equal to total costs, is used to value the benefits. Expenditure data by functional categories disaggregated down to departmental levels help in the alloca- tion of benefits to various income groups. The incidence of taxation in Thailand expressed through effective tax rates in 1963 and 1969 shows a generally regressive pattern under a money income base, with the lowest income bracket bearing the highest relative tax burdens and the highest bracket the lowest relative tax burdens. Under the adjusted income base, however, the tax incidence becomes alumst proportional due to the fact that the income levels of tflue lower income brackets under this income base are relatively Inuch higher than the income levels under a money income base. flaring the tax 5 ‘ , ‘ b 1“.~.I-|O ....., L‘ .:;.': -6 9 Sins” 5:232:11; than the - 7... ~ ‘1’ 2:312:31 a‘...;CDt 1.. _::::'.::3. ‘ncier an :.--: J. 1969' hla’fi'c .‘A ‘l a :-.:.-1' .333 thVSe N u»... ‘I‘QWQYPN ‘ witr' t:‘ " 3 ‘11:. ‘\I‘ W“. ‘ I‘Licn 1n "“ "5:3“, ~ ‘ 1 mail. "a; \.. :‘I‘ A: ' ‘1" AL‘ \u‘la‘~ . o flees 1n ~L. ._: ‘ Pu - f‘~. ‘ 2‘: ~V~ “DAVIL "l N.- UquOV- H ":5 y ‘\ D “.9. v. i ”Ste: 5 Medhi Krongkaew Comparing the tax systems of 1963 and 1969, the latter ap- pears to be slightly less regressive, thus less income de- equalizing than the former. Expenditure incidence assumes a pattern almost identical to tax incidence, that is, it is generally regressive under a money income base and almost pro- portional under an adjusted income base. The expenditure pro- grams of 1969, however, appear to be much more regressive or pro-poor than those of 1963, this enabling the net benefits (expenditure benefits minus tax burdens) in 1969 to accrue to lower-income households relatively more than the net benefits in 1963. Therefore, while the net fiscal incidence pattern in 1963 ranged from slightly regressive to slightly progres- sive under money and adjusted income, respectively, the net fiscal incidence in 1969 was regressive under both income bases, indicating that fiscal programs in 1969 helped improve the distribution of income of the Thai households, while fis- cal programs in 1963 left the distribution of income in that year more or less unchanged. However, the degree of improvement in income equality (or a reduction in income inequality) from 1969 to 1963 was still very small. In terms of the Gini concentration ratio, which is used extensively in this study to evaluate the de- gree of changes in the patterns of pre-fisc, post-tax, post- benefit, and post-fisc income distribution, the post-fisc in- come distribution in 1969 improved by about 2.3 to 3.8 percent over the post-fisc income distribution in 1963. The government can effect this much improvement simply by imposing an extra ;.i:e::e:1t tax en t: ...' 2”er , .. ; u- ._...:.u utlflg tut V... .- A a k 5". . " " Y?,,V1'b’ hue i no- 0".va bu n . -. .'-:‘ :nA :1 r'-,-\ r u ...¢..A.Au . - :1...‘ &l ”:3:““€flq ftat "‘“""“UB-V .9"\-‘b ‘ u . .4 \L‘I F i u I: (D *4 '1 (I) O I?) 0 >8 . . "-~... ‘ "H 4 “A u. .«utta tin :‘ . l 2’ _. v ‘ .n- -.~h R"- ‘ ‘ "‘ '1. ”A "o Abd=LIAU¢M 'II- ...’ " \ 9 H . «A . ~u b a “h VA "ublf .:_I °.. a“. “a. Na ‘_ ‘ Uu‘ . Q ' P . ““- CE’l,~ ‘ V .k I ' -.:' ‘v-_ ' y L- A“ ~.\... A“ . ~~ith O: ‘L‘ k 5‘1 .. "‘\~'-' A. 1- r3 Medhi Krongkaew 2.5 percent tax on the income of the highest income bracket and distributing the tax revenue to the poorest income class. More important, the above conclusion that the fiscal programs in Thailand helped reduce income inequality is true only under the assumption that a budget deficit, which was present in both 1963 and 1969, adds directly to the income of households without their suffering any reduction in real income through possible price increases due to the existence of such a defi- cit. When this assumption is changed so that the budget deficit causes the price level to rise, which adversely af— fects each household equally, then the fiscal programs in both 1963 and 1969 could be shown to be income de-equalizing instead of income equalizing. In conclusion, depending on certain assumptions con- cerning budget deficit, the Thai government could be shown to have contributed very little or none at all to the reduction in income inequality in the six years from 1963 to 1969. In the presence of the still considerable income disparities, policy changes are strongly advocated in the areas of basic tax reforms and increased specific and transfer expenditures. "2": “an RE O sun t‘VVow RED FUEL] THE INCOME REDISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF TAXES AND PUBLIC EXPENDITURES IN THAILAND: AN INTERTEMPORAL STUDY BY Medhi Krongkaew A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1975 ©Copyright by MEDHI KRONGKAEW 1975 - 0-. To my Children, Bee and Ben, and my Wife, Kanlaya ii I wish to 3’:°;..~ ;. v. k u“ ‘_ d lvll-v ““: ‘ ‘ ‘ 3 ti. “triifiim an': tn u :" u.- ' ... r. ‘ + - ‘ -wir . chalca‘ .. ~ "-g '--.'~“ fiv- -."-.u‘ ' I T - ‘ . ‘ an l“Gest L. AS I H Etaa~*ed :1: '=-.YE:S‘: I". "3! t0 Dr . - I ‘5 tall and AC 37.5: 1 u 3. ‘m 1 . v Jr. Lily Y 54:: Mean “d 5 Se .fffih m- D! £4Adm'zasé :‘ In. a . 4,915 ‘ 3‘ fatil Eight '1', ”I SPECial ‘“*a:; . Coilcan ‘4 . _, .- .5 Drlginal - I‘AU ‘ ‘1 1’ s, ‘ . "'~‘ 9-. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I wish to express my sincere gratitude to Professor Milton C. Taylor, my thesis advisor, for his invaluable advice, encouragement and guidance, kindness and under- standing during the difficult time when this study was being undertaken; and to Professors Warren J. Samuels, Byron W. Brown, and Daniel H. Saks, members of my thesis committee, for their technical assistance, constructive comments and suggestions, and encouragement. I am indebted to Thammasat University whose scholar- ship has enabled me to pursue my study at Michigan State University; to Dr. Puey Ungphakorn, Acharn Sangwian Intravichai, and Acharn Montri Borisuth, who were instru- mental in the establishment and operation of this scholar- ship; to Dr. Lily Kosiyanon and Acharn Temchai Suwannathat, present dean and secretary, respectively, of the Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, who readily made available all kinds of facilities while I was doing my research in Bangkok. My special thanks go to Dr. Oey Astra Meesook, my friend and colleague, who liberally and selflessly provided numerous original data from her study for use in this study, and to Dr. Ammar Siamwala who gave several helpful suggestions and comments. iii Finally, I v 21:52:53, and moral 2:23:3‘ he time I .. . ‘ :09;Q-0q“ - N a ’ uu.v.¢uuatel}’ qu- Finally, I wish to thank my family for their love, patience, and moral support both during the time I was with them and the time I was away; To them, this work is affectionately dedicated. iv LIES? TABLES . . "u .. ‘ t “'i .1 OI *ISURES . 0"“ f‘ y-nm'r‘" ““P‘UDUki l.J-‘ Purpose 0 Interest The Case The Govern Tax and 2.. Fiscal Inc' Elites Bureauc ix;endi O A 99. w- T g .- ~ .‘._. . \ — TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Chapter I. II. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Purpose of the Study . . . . . . . . . Interest in Income Distribution . . . . The Case for Economic Equality . . . The Government as Income Redistributor Tax and Expenditure Incidence Studies Fiscal Incidence Study in Thailand . . Elites . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bureaucracy . . . . . . . . . . . . . Expenditure Policies . . . . . . . . Development Policy . . . . . . . . Banking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Procedure of the Study . . . . . . . . General Procedure . . . . . . . . . . Specific Procedure . . . . . . . . . Limitations of the Study . . . . . . . Plan of the Study . . . . . . . . . . . THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME IN THAILAND: 1963 AND 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . Conceptual and Statistical Problems in Estimating the Income Distribution . Past Studies of Income Distribution in Thailand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Income Distribution in 1963 . . . . . . Nature of Data and Method of Study The Income Distribution Estimates . . Income Distribution in 1969 . . . . . . Nature of Data and Method of Study . The Income Distribution Estimates . . Comparison between the 1963 and 1969 Distributions of Income . . . . . . . Page ix xiii 33 34 39 41 41 43 53 53 56 61 Incone Di 1963 an Statistic Inequal AdjuStments Personal Income 1: .2- 7\“Yv\—‘. ‘ ““4 AJK, lainlgz Theoretical Studies AGQI‘aral ‘ Tile kfialyS Iniivid; CDIPOra: Business SeleCt 3181:: 5919:: lipart I? >1 m'EJ >1.) '9) fl- III. IV. Income Distribution by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . Statistical Measures of Income Inequality . . . . . . . . . . . . Adjustments in the Income Concept . . . . Personal Income . . . . . . . . . . . . Income in Kind . . . . . . . . . . Net Corporate Retained Earnings . . Indirect Taxes . . . . . . . The Adjusted Income Concept . . Summary and Conclusion . . . . THE INCIDENCE OF TAXES . . . . . . . . . Theoretical Problems in Tax Incidence Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . A General Methodology . . . . . . . . Selection of Taxes . . . . . . . . . Allocation of Tax Burdens . . . . . . . The Analysis of Taxes . . . . . . . . . . Individual Income Tax . . . . . . . Corporate Income Tax . . . . . . . Business Taxes and Stamp Duties; Selective Sales Taxes; Import Duties Business Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . Selective Sales taxes . . . . . ._. . Import Duties . . . . . . . . . . . Export Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . Taxes on Property . . . . . . . . . . . Royalties and Permits; Government Sales and Services: Government Enterprises and MonOpolies; and Other Miscellaneous Revenues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Empirical Results of Tax Analysis . . . Effective Tax Rates by Income Classes The Effects of Tax Programs on the Distribution of Income . . . . . . Summary and Conclusion . . . . . . . . THE INCIDENCE OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES . . . Theoretical Problems in Expenditure Incidence Studies . .‘. . . . . . . . . Money Flow versus Benefit Approach . . Direct and Indirect Recipients of Benefits . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Measurement of Benefits . . . . . Expenditure Beneficiaries and the "Spendee" Concept . . . . . . . . . vi Page 62 66 72 73 77 79 81 82 89 99 100 103 104 109 112 112 114 117 119 119 120 120 122 123 126 129 140 145 152 153 154 155 157 161 A General Select: Allocat Group I: I Agricul Power :. Transp ' Other i. Group 2: Primar‘ Second: Higner Vocati Serv: GIOup 3; Group 4; A General Methodology . . . . . . . . . . Selection of Public Expenditures . . . Allocation of Public Expenditures Group 1: Economic Services . . . . . . . Agriculture . . . . . . . . .1. . . . . Power and Fuels, and Industries . . . . Transportation and Communication . . . Other Economic Services . . . . . . . Group 2: Educational Services . . . . . Primary Education . . . . . . . . . . . Secondary Education . . . . . . . . . . Higher Education . . . . . . Vocational and Other Educational Services . . . . . . . . . . . Group 3: Health and Social Welfare . . . Group 4: General Services . . . . . . . Defense . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Law Enforcement . . . . . . . . . . . Public Administration . . . . . . Other Miscellaneous Expenditures Group 5: Interest Payments on the Public Debt . . . . . . . . . Empirical Results of Expenditure Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Effective Expenditure Rates by Income Classes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Effects of Expenditure Programs on the Distribution of Income . . . . Summary and Conclusion . . . . . . . . V. THE NET FISCAL INCIDENCE . . . . . . . Effective Fiscal Rates or Net Fiscal Incidence by Income Classes . . . . The Effects of Fiscal Activities on the Distribution of Income . . . . . . . Budget Deficit in Fiscal Incidence Studies. Summary and Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . VI. SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS, AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary of Purpose and Procedures . . . . . Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Tax Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Expenditure Incidence . . . . . . . . . . Net Fiscal Incidence . . . . . . . . . . Policy Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . On the Tax Side . . . . . . . . . . . . . On the Expenditure Side . . . . . . . . . Suggestions for Further Research . . . Vii Page 163 165 169 169 169 174 175 182 182 184 185 185 186 187 189 190 191 192 193 194 196 200 212 215 225 226 235 241 251 258 258 263 263 264 266 270 270 271 273 .u-‘qvt‘n Staten... o I t O ‘. .. “to“ . - .uuuloa -. at: :“N. . . “ ’ u...) B‘DYY N“- The Estimati in 1963 . Basic Data f Income Dis 5' . 228 Estimat; Distributiv: Expenditu: I‘— 2- . me Act F15 Maren: Ud‘ drlx‘h‘: Page APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 277 Appendix A. The Estimation of the Number of Households in 1963 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 277 B. Basic Data for the Estimation of the Money Income Distribution in 1969 . . . . . . . . 280 C. The Estimation of Income in Kind in 1963 . . 286 D. Distributive Series for Use as Tax and Expenditure Allocation Bases . . . . . . . 290 E. Disaggregated Tax Data . . . . . . . . . . . 299 F. Disaggregated Expenditure Data . . . . . . . 306 G. The Lorenz Functions of Various Distributions Of Income 0 O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 312 H. The Net Fiscal Incidence Based on the Aaron-» McGuire-Maital Method . . . . . . . . . . . 315 SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 322 viii . I: - .L.C by Inc Househ . . 8L1: Distri ‘stribut .0‘. ‘ House} UlS‘v' .H‘ C r h. t I S l Table 2.1 LIST OF TABLES Page Percentage Distribution of Families by Income Classes from the 1962—1963 Household Expenditure Survey . . . . . . . 45 Distribution of Money Income by Annual Income Classes from Household Expenditure Survey, 1962-1963 . . . . . . 46 Distribution of Total Families and Total Family Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 O O O O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 52 Distribution of Money Income of Urban Households, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . 58 Distribution of Money Income of Rural Households, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . 59 Distribution of Money Income of National Households, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . 60 A Comparison between Distribution of National Money Income in 1963 and 1969, by Income Classes . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 Distribution of Adjusted Income, by Income Elements, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . 83 Distribution of Adjusted Income, by Income Elements, by Income Classes, 1963 . . . . 84 Total Adjusted Taxes and Other Government Revenues, by Type, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . 108 Distribution of Absolute Tax Burdens by Income Classes, 1963 . . . . . . . . . . . 127 Distribution of Adsolute Tax Burdens by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . 128 ix L4 Effective It by Incone Income, I Effective Te Income, t Generalized Percentage E Post-Tax Income C} a . . . .1. (—1) Pr€~Fisc and Inequalit Total Aij‘ds: Thailand, u U-GV‘A' ‘ X C..‘lture CH! ‘1 ‘ C a,” M I I,‘ ~“E’C‘1'”e *— B1,, Elfin L 01y“ndlt II My” J x. Table 3.4 3.5 3.7 3.8 3.9 3.10 Effective Tax Rates Based on Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 . . . . . . . Effective Tax Rates Based on Money Income, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . Effective Tax Rates Based on Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 . . . Effective Tax Rates Based on Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . Generalized Tax Incidence Functions Percentage Distribution of Pre-Fisc and Post-Tax Money and Adjusted Income by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . . . Pre-Fisc and Post-Tax Gini Concentration Ratios and Percentage Changes in Income Inequality, 1963 and 1969 . . . . Total Adjusted Public Expenditures of Thailand, by Functional Categories, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . Distribution of Highway Benefits Assigned to Trucked Transport, by Allocation Bases, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . Expenditure Benefits, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, 1963 Expenditure Benefits, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, 1969 Effective Expenditure Rates, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on Money Income, 1963 . . . . . . Effective Expenditure Rates, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on Money Income, 1969 ’. . . . . . Effective Expenditure Rates, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on Adjusted Income, 1963 . . . . . . . Page 130 131 132 133 139 141 143 168 181 198 199 201 202 203 . _ \L“ O D a 1...) Effective E Expendit on Adjus Generalizei :3 Percentage Post-Ben by Incom Pre-Fisc an Ratios a Inequali Absolute 59 Effective F Adjusted Assumpti amneralized Percentaae POSt'Fis Income C ASSUfipti Table Page 4.8 Effective Expenditure Rates, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on Adjusted Income, 1969 . . . . . . . . . 204 4.9 Generalized Expenditure Incidence Functions . 210 4.10 Percentage Distribution of Pre-Fisc and Post-Benefit Money and Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . 213 4.11 Pre—Fisc and Post-Benefit Gini Concentration Ratios and Percentage Changes in Income Inequality, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . 214 5.1 Absolute Net Fiscal Incidence, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 227 5.2 Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Money and Adjusted Income, 1963 and 1969: Assumption I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228 5.3 Generalized Net Fiscal Incidence Functions . 234 5.4 Percentage Distribution of Pre-Fisc and Post-Fisc Money and Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969: Assumption I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 236 5.5 Pre-Fisc and Post-Fisc Gini Concentration Ratios and Percentage Changes in Income Inequality, 1963 and 1969: Assumption I . 238 5.6 Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Money and Adjusted Income, 1963 and 1969: Assumption II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 246 5.7 Percentage Distribution of Pre-Fisc and Post-Fisc Money and Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969: Assumption III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 247 5.8 Pre-Fisc and Post-Fisc Gini Concentration Ratios and Percentage Changes in Income Inequality, 1963 and 1969: Assumption III C C O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O 250 A.1 Estimated POpulation in 1963 . . . . . . . . 278 A.2 Estimated Number of Households in 1963 . . . 279 xi I I - k) {‘4 , tAJ Number of H; Areas, 15 Percentage I Househol: Percentage I by IDCOI‘A Percentage l by Incoz. Average Urb. Classes, Average Rur. Classes, km Average Table Page B.l Number of Households in Urban and Rural Areas, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 281 B.2 Percentage Distribution of Urban and Rural Households by Regions, 1969 . . . . . . . 281 3.3 Percentage Distribution of Urban Households by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . 282 8.4 Percentage Distribution of Rural Households by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . 283 B.5 Average Urban Annual Money Income, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 284 B.6 Average Rural Annual Money Income, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 285 C.1 The Average Income in Kind, by Locations, by Income Classes, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . 287 C.2 The Estimated Income in Kind Regression Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 288 C.3 Total Income in Kind, 1963 . . . . . . . . . 289 0.1 Distributive Series, 1963 . . . . . . . . . . 291 D.2 Distributive Series, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . 292 D.3 Total Household Expenditures, 1963 . . . . . 293 D.4 Total Household Expenditures, 1969 . . . . . 294 E.1 Disaggregated Taxes and Other Revenues, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 299 F.1 Disaggregated Public Expenditures, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 306 G.l Lorenz Functions of Various Distributions of Income, 1963 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 313 G.2 Lorenz Functions of Various Distributions of Income, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 314 H.l Comparison of the Post-Fisc Distribution of Income Based on Aaron-McGuire-Maital Method and Methods Used in This Study . . 320 xii al! N) Distributi; 1963 an. EffECtiVe ' by Inco: by Inca: 7.“: ‘. “*~eCt‘Ve 1 Income, Effective 1 Income, Effecti‘re I by ITICQf n:- u«:ectiY'Ve I Figure 3.1 3.2 4.2 5.1 5.2 LIST OF FIGURES Distribution of Money Income in Thailand, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . A Hypothetical Lorenz Curve . . . . . . . . . Distribution of Adjusted Income in Thailand, 1963 and 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . Effective Tax Rates Based on Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . Effective Tax Rates Based on Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . . . Effective Expenditure Rates Based on Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 Effective Expenditure Rates Based on Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Adjusted Income, by Income Classes, 1963 and 1969 . xiii Page 65 69 85 136 137 207 208 231 232 3345 known as a I::I: .A‘ ' . 1 ‘ : ' .uv:_:~n “1&1 c ‘ ' z."fl~ D“ r“~.d' e. 4 'rhaSis 0- I.‘.; ‘ ~., '..‘:: g0".°V:-1:‘ ‘ ': l‘icg‘c “Ah/W a-~ a.n'\";“ J :Z::‘n ‘ 'i.‘-I§b‘res' es: t h. ' ‘v” ‘G l a the fact VE‘:\‘ ‘ 1‘: fire Gena} "it in. t \.reases :- ‘ . ‘ srCSPEr \z. «II ‘1 C.t . 5‘ . ‘ “ ls ¥} :‘I‘2‘E‘H‘mA "‘5'“ v I 90 Jer: :Q .‘ ‘ . “swig? CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Purpose of the Study The purpose of this study is to estimate the income redistributional impact of the government tax and expendi- ture policies in Thailand in 1963 and 1969 and between these two years. In the economics of public finance, this is basi- cally known as a fiscal incidence study. However, the present research will differ from the conventional incidence study by placing emphasis more upon the interyear income redistribu- tional effects than upon the effects of government fiscal ac- tivities within a single year. There is a need to understand more about the extent to which governments have helped equalize the distribution of income among individuals or households through taxes and expenditures, especially in underdeveloped countries. In view of the fact that income distribution obviously has not become more equal in many developing countries, despite ap- parent increases in the national income and other indices of economic prosperity, certain questions have been asked: To what extent is the public sector responsible? Is there a deliberate government policy not to improve the distribution of income? Or is the government merely disinterested in or "=Cti'Je concerni 5:22": will attexp 1:21 governmen Before pr: grassnt research, Lrationale of ‘ tires: in income < 3:11 fecus on the ;::::e equality oz 3 3115 issue, In recent inactive concerning the income distribution issues? This study will attempt to answer these questions in the context cfi'Thai government policy in and between the years 1963 and 1969. Before proceeding to the scope and procedure of the present research, this chapter will discuss the background and rationale of the study. Following an account of the in- terest in income distribution in recent years, discussion will focus on the case for action being taken in regard to income equality or redistribution and the role of government in this issue. Interest in Income Distribution In recent years there has been a tremendous increase in interest in the economics of income distribution. This Shift from a preoccupation with resource allocation and 9T0Wth is quite timely because the problem of persistent and W'OISening inequality in the distribution income throughout the'world has begun to cry for attention. An understanding ofthe nature of income distribution, the causes of maldis- tribution, and possible solutions is sorely needed. Unlike the study of functional income distribution orthe distribution of factor shares, the systematic study C” Personal distribution of income by size has a relatively recent history. Work began in the 19405 with a few studies in England and the United States. Soon after, an interest inunderdeveloped economies began to emerge. The year 1954 gritzei one of the ::::e distributi £52331 Address t 51:: Kuznets exp i;s::i':ution in d 3:3;i0neerin-g st ‘; Liferdevelopcd ‘u. -.-r. that in deve N. ..... ..;...:s in income etczczic developrfi Interest L 13535, but re-emez 153‘ Era, the Worlr x; .n the ecm ""33351‘] altere 7.11.5: interest )1 1972 The st: marked one of the earliest attempts by an economist to study imxmm distribution in underdeveloped nations. In his Presi- dentfifl.Address to the American Economic Association in 1954, Shmanuznets expressed his concern about the state of income cfistribution in developed as well as underdeveloped countries. Ifis pioneering study, which concluded that income distribution blunderdeveloped nations was less equal (or more unequal) than that in developed countries, paved the way for further research.by Irving Kravis in 1960 and Harry Oshima in 1962.2 B11963 Kuznets published another study dealing with the Changes in income distribution through historical phases of economic development, which is now a classic in the field.3 Interest in income distribution lagged in the late 19608. but re-emerged in the early 19705. As if heralding a new era, the World Bank, which previously had been concerned onlY‘mith the economic growth aspect of poor nations, con- SEficuously altered its attitude and policy and manifested greater interest in more equitable income distribution among 'thOSe\ ".38. :. t E cat -«.._8 Of a C In .~‘av ‘ Ml equlm .Q . . . 1.: '7 ...butive C 3‘.“ c “e 0. the 5. RA“": W‘s. af“ - VHUall“ 5'5 50:1 e at th: :I“ “QJJSis ‘ h. ' I wnlc _ \ s,“ "at: 4;, ““ IV ‘U‘ V as A t;n~ “a|'al inc . L'nt Whir, eff. of) St; 3‘]: K. 24 data are available which are broken down on the same basis; only the national data are available. Therefore, these taxes and expenditures cannot be allocated at any other level, un- less, of course, one is willing to make risky assumptions as to which parts of the taxes and expenditures may be attributed to the several regions. As for the exclusion of certain local government fiscal activities, these are small, fragmented en- tities, and they tend to exist on a quid pro quo basis, that is, the services they provide are available only to those who pay for them. As a result, the income distributive effects are likely to be neutral. However, central government grants- in-aid to these local governments were considered in this study because they were part of general government expendi- tures. Finally, it is recognized that the true distributive effects of a fiscal policy can be measured only through a general equilibrium analysis which takes into account all distributive components and reactions. Given the present state of the art, however, it is not conceivable that one could actually measure all such effects. The most that can be done at the present time is to use partial equilibrium analysis, which considers only primary and direct impact, other things remaining constant or neutral. De Wulf, a critic of fiscal incidence studies, has realized this problem:38 Until general equilibrium models are built which allow researchers to trace the full effects of wholesale budget substitution on income distribution, partial incidence studies are much more reliable guides than system incidence studies. The r yereference hrshich rea :mnin Thail tereferehce justzehts in is: such an e alseries of ixa,althcug :2: 1962 and iata after 19 25 Plan of the Study The main reason for selecting 1963 and 1969 as the two reference years was that these were the only two years for which reasonable data for estimating the income distribu— tion in Thailand were available. It is possible to stretch the reference interval farther than six years by making ad- justments in the income data, but there is no valid reason for such an expansion at the expense of abandoning two origi- nal series of data. Moreover, the 1963 tax and expenditure data, although imperfect, are decidedly better than those for 1962 and earlier years. In addition, the details of some data after 1969 were unavailable. Therefore, the choice of 1963 and 1969 appears to serve the purpose of this study well. The remainder of this study is divided into five chapters. Chapter 2 will be concerned with estimating the income distribution of Thailand in 1963 and 1969. Different income concepts will be explored and adjustments made so as to have a more complete income base for the study. Chapter 3 will consider the tax incidence in Thailand in 1963 and 1969, and Chapter 4 will compute the incidence or benefits of public expenditures for these years. Chapter 5 will con- solidate Chapters 3 and 4, and the net results of the entire effects of the Thai fiscal system for the two reference years will be estimated. In this chapter, attention will be given to such matters as deficit financing, which have been neg- lected in many incidence studies, but which will receive relativelY mor 52 possible to iistribution 0 aresult of <30 521:5 subst at has done littl varicus househ its upper to t In the sizzle study wi 53: reducing i :e-w.‘ ' :.a.Cfl dire-c 26 relatively more attention here. From this chapter, it will be possible to determine whether any change occurred in the distribution of income between the two reference periods as a result of government budgetary policies, or whether the re- sults substantiate the hypothesis that the Thai government has done little or nothing in redistributing income among various households in the desired direction, that is, from the upper to the lower income classes. In the last chapter, the substantive content of the whole study will be summarized, certain policy implications for reducing income inequality will be discussed, and future research directions will be indicated. 1See 5: Kibdtiontn A71 ER. Heraftei trzzation by 51 2Irving Discritutiori o: 42 {Haverber , IrenitiOhal ( :xeswith Spec xiStatistics. . Simon .xsdlof Kati: -‘A I ”‘vn2r 1 " , -c betel: 3 H .. n U u h"fir‘ ' 5;::E£'(“35 Jk‘fi‘kr“ shynficp q ‘ ‘rin "L, 19,1] .s‘ql‘tlon apd I V ‘ ‘5}an fl ‘ -. r r REVISE V :" it- .u‘k‘7~k "5...; vdSed T “‘1‘“ Av. ‘ s‘V 1‘ gay _ Jfient a'. FOOTNOTES lSee Simon Kuznets, "Economic Growth and Income Dis- tribution," American Economic Review, 45 (March, 1955), pp. 1-28. Herafter, by income distribution is meant income dis- tribution by size unless otherwise specified. 2Irving B. Kravis, "International Differences in the Distribution of Income," Review of Economics and Statistics, 42 (November, 1960), pp. 408-416; Harry T. Oshima, “The International Comparison of Size Distribution of Family In- comes with Special Reference to Asia," Review of Economics and Statistics, 44 (November, 1962), pp. 439-45. 3Simon Kuznets, "Quantitative Aspects of Economic Growth of Nations: III, Distribution of Income by Size," Economic Development and Cultural Change, 2 (January, 1963), pp. 1-80. 4Robert McNamara, "The Environmental Dilemma" in War on Hunger, (Washington, D. C.: U. S. Department of State, December, 1971) as quoted in Richard Weisskoff, "Income Dis- tribution and Economic Growth in Puerto Rico, Argentina, and Mexico," Review of Income and Wealth, 16 (December, 1970), P. 327. 5Robert McNamara, "Address to the Board of Governors," IBRD/IMF Annual meeting, Nairobi, September 24, 1973, p. 11. 6Idem., "Address to the Board of Governors" IBRD/IMF Annual meeting, Washington, D. C., September 25, 1972, p. 15. 7One of the most forceful arguments in favor of equity-based development policy is found in Mahbub ul Huq, "Employment and Income Distribution in the 19705: A New Perspective," a statement prepared for the Society for Inter- national Development 12th World Conference, Ottawa, May 16- 19, 1971. 8See, for example, Irma Adelman and Cynthia Taft Morris, "An Anatomy of Patterns of Income Distribution in Developing Nations," paper prepared for USAID, Washington, D. C., February, 1971; Felix Paukert, "Income Distribution at Different Levels of Development: A Survey of Evidence," International Labour Review, 108 (August-September, 1973), pp. 97-125; Irving B. Kravis, "A World of Unequal Incomes," The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social 27 3:1 sce3409 (E mien for Pr-c‘ections, E asaagkok, l972 Some Dimensior Eollis Chener) Chapter 1. 9See v ("re .lsrals of 1s to retrace gznal producti 3. real terms: .19 rate Of pr :1: 53' K: "sz 9 Y equals 3’03 which it 28 Science,409 (September, 1973), pp. 61-80; U. N., Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East, Interregional Trade Projections, Effective Protection, and Income Distribution: (Bangkok, 1972); Montek S. Ahluwalia,“Income Inequality: Some Dimensions of the Problem," Redistribution with Growth, Hollis Chenery et a1. (London: Oxford University Press, 1974), Chapter 1. —_ __ 9See Walter A. Weisskopf, "The Dialectics of Equality," The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973). P. 167. 10Edward J. Nell has shown that one way to prove this is to retrace the usual neoclassical exposition of the mar- ginal productivity theory. Start with the income identity in real terms: Y = wN + rK (l) where Y is output; w, the wage; N, the number of workers; r, the rate of profit; and K, the total capital stock. Divide (1) by K: y = wn + r (2) where y equals Y/K and n equals N/K. Differentiate: dy = ndw 4 wdn + dr (3) from which it follows that w = dy/dn (4) or the wage will equal the marginal product of labor if and only if -n equals dr/dw, that is, all sectors in the economy must have the same capital to output ratios which is a most unlikely circumstance. In general, with a given technique or if the techniques vary, the wage may not equal the marginal product of labor because the real wage rate and profit rate will move haphazardly as the relative scarcity of labor to capital varies. See Edward J. Nell, "The Fall of the House of Efficiency," The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973). pp. 102-111. For a larger discussion on this "reswitching" point, see George C. Harcourt, Some Cambridge Controversies in The Theory of Capital (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972). 11Matthew Arnold, Lecture on "Equality" in Mixed Essa 5, ed. 1903, p. ix, quoted by R. H. Tawney, Equality 4th ed.. (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1964), p. 33. 12R. H. Tawney, supra. l3See tic. (Cambrid Fulton Fried: of Chicago Pr. 14Bar 2: Income and Acaderv of Po 15 . Mil Distribution . I.‘-.u;ust, 1953 1 i6TO heds X and tion. x is :cral worth isles, and consumption 2113: be inher 56259 that no 520 that X ta- 393. that is | ‘AOJ‘C mu 33: c. “twr of: .th .‘v .. how 1 29 13See Bertrand de Jouvenel, The Ethics of Redistribu- tion (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951) and Milton Friedman, Capital and Freedom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962). 14Harry G. Johnson, "Some Microeconomic Reflections on Income and Wealth Inequalities," The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973), p. 60. 15Milton Friedman, "Choice, Chance, and the Personal Distribution of Income," Journal of Political Economy, 61 (August, 1953), 277-90. 16To further elaborate upon Rawls' View, two sets of goods X and y, may be conceived in a consumer's utility func- tion. X is a set of primary social goods where liberty and moral worth (basic rights and duties) are often cited as ex- amples, and y is a set of ordinary commodities for physical consumption and enjoyment. Rawls' system requires that x must be inherently equal for everyone in the society in the sense that none in society has more than the least endowed, and that x takes precedence over y in a lexicographical man- ner, that is to say, an individual with (x2 Y1) is always I better off than with (x1 Y2) no matter how small (x2 - x1) or how large (Y2 - Y1) is. The inequality in income and wealth or difference in Y2 and Y1 in the above model is "just" only when it is agreed upon or sanctioned by a democratic approval within a hypothetical "original situation," that is, the situation where no one has a preconceived idea of where he stands in the society or in Bronfenbrenner's interpretation, none knows either his relative standing in such attributes as IQ and physical stamina or what the relative social standing of his particular race, sex, religion or age group may be. Then, the next requirement in Rawls' system is that the least ad- vantaged members of society deserve to be compensated first and foremost. See John Rawls, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 1971), p. 14, 60, 302-3, passim. See also Martin Bronfenbrenner, "Equity and Equality," The Angals of the American_Academy_of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973), pp. 9 - 23, 17One of such view is found in W. Arthur Lewis, The Theory of Economic Growth (London: Allen and Unwin, 1955). 18See W. Paul Strassmann, "Economic Growth and Income Distribution," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 (August, 1956), pp. 425- 40; William G. Tyler, "A Model of Income Dis- tribution and Economic Development," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, (1973). PP. 321-36. feund in Alb. 3:22 Inequal "arterlv JO‘ L____+_ II ct. ZZHO: ‘hat while t] i‘ith equalize :crthodox "5 stiztlate grc tribution anc p Pb K 1 [ 'A'n‘ V‘wn. , a. «CIC‘O‘J.:EI 23Ri< 26.. 3" 1110. ." H. a .I “Q L1 '~\-. T ‘ Jtur' nyuliczlcs ar; A; ’ ! 30 19William R. Cline, Potential Effects of Income Re- distribution on Economic Growth: Latin American cases (New York: Prager, 1972). 20Kuznet, "Quantitative...," pp. 78-80. 21An interesting analysis of this tolerance level is found in Albert 0. Hirschman, "The Changing Tolerance for In- come Inequality in the Course of Economic Development," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (November, 1973), pp. 544- 66. 2However, W. R. Cline in his recent article contends that while the orthodox fear of a decline in the savings rate with equalization has been found empirically doubtful, the unorthodox "structuralist" hope that redistribution would stimulate growth has also been found dubious. See his "Dis- tribution and Development: Survey of Literature," Journal of Development Economics, 1 (February, 1975), pp. 359—400. 23Richard A. Musgrave, The Theory of Public Finance (New York: McGraw Hill, 1959). 24See Ralph Miliband, The State in Capitalist Society (New York: Basic Books, 1969); Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy, Monopoly Capital (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966); Richard C. Edwards, Michael Reich, and Thomas E. Weisskopf, The Capitalist System (Englewood, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1972); James A. O'Connor, The Fiscal Crisis of the State (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1973); and somewhat in dif- ferent context, J. Kenneth Galbraith, The New Industrial State, 2nd ed., rev. (Boston: Houghton-Mifflin, 1971). 25 O'Connor, pp. 6-7. 26Thomas E. Weisskopf "Capitalism, Underdevelopment, and the Future of the Poor Countries" in Jagdish Bhagwati, ed., Economics and World Order (London: MacMillan, 1972), p. 40. 27John Kenneth Galbraith, "Power and the Useful Econo- mist," American Economic Review, 63 (March, 1973), pp. 10-11. 28Some authors use the word "progressive expenditure" to mean the expenditure which benefits the lower income groups relatively more as the income level falls. Therefore, this has the same meaning as "regressive expenditure" used in this study. This latter choice of word is preferable because it is consistent with the treatment on the tax side. 29Mabel Newcomer, "Estimates of the Tax Burden on Different Income Classes": Studies in Current Tax Problems (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1937), pp. 1-52; Helen pp. 1' of .Ex Z'Pa. mem fiaticnal Tax C Journal. 4 (5‘ OTibc Public Finance .. leave} Kingdom," Rev: 1353). p.073: here in Post 1.__________ ..... 310. l Tuesand Pub] J...s ness ‘ eDistrit Lsss in Fisc Hsslnstituti :xstr ib utior 31 Tarasov, "Who Pays the Taxes?" TNEC - Monograph No. 3, 76th Congress 3rd Session, Washington, D. C., 1941; Helen Tarasov "Who Does Pay the Taxes?" Social Research, Supplement IV (1942), pp. 1-79; Richard A. Musgrave et a1., "Distribution of Tax Payments by Income Class: A Case Study for 1948" NationaltTax Journal, 4 (March, 1951), pp. 1-53; Rufus S. Tucker, "Distribution of Tax Burdens in 1948," National Tax Journal, 4 (September, 1951), pp. 269-85. 30Tibor Barna, The Redistribution of Incomes Through Public Finance in 1937 (Oxford: The Clarendon Press, 1945); Findley Weaver, “Taxation and Redistribution in the United Kingdom,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 32 (August, 1950), pp. 201-13; Allan M. Cartter, The Redistribution of Income in Postwar Britain (New Haven! Yale University Press, 1955). 31O. H. Brownlee, "Estimated Distribution of Minnesota Taxes and Public Expenditure Benefits," Studies in Economics and Business No. 21 (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota, 1960); W. Irwin Gillespie, "Effects of Public Expenditures on the Distribution of Income," in Richard A. Musgrave,ed. Essays in Fiscal Federalism, (Washington, D. C.: The Brook- ings Institution, 1965), pp. 122-86; Neil M. Singer, "Income Redistribution through the Federal Budget in 1959f unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1965; The Tax Founda- tion, Tax Burdens and Benefits of Government Expenditure by Income Class, 1961 and 1965 (New York: The Tax Foundation, _ 1967). 3 - 32John Adler, E. R. Schlesinger, and Ernest Olson, Public Finance and Economic Development in Guatemala (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1952); Henry Wallich and John Adler Public Finance in a Developing Country: E1 Salvador-~A Case Study (Cambridge: Harvard UniversiEy Press, 1951); Carl S. Shoup 33 a1., The Fiscal System of Venezuela: A Report (Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press, 1959). 33These countries include: Argentina, Brazil, Chile Colombia, Jamaica, Panama, Peru, Puerto Rico, Surinam, India, Greece, Indonesia, Kenya, Lebanon, Malawi, Pakistan, Philippines, Tanzania, Turkey, and West Malaysia. For comprehensive sur- veys on tax, expenditure and budget incidence studies in less developed countries see Richard M. Bird and Luc De Wulf, "Taxa— tion and Income Distribution in Latin America: A Critical Review of the Empirical Studies" International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 23 (November, 1973). Pp. 639-682; L. De Wulf, "Fiscal Incidence Studies in Developing Countries: Survey and Critique," IMF Staff Papers, 22 (March, 1975), pp. 61-131; see also Jacob Meerman,fiFiscal Incidence in Empirical Studies of Income Distribution in Poor Countries" AID Discussion Paper No. 25, (Washington, D. C., December, 1972). ' 31 if the Ta: tion in L. are held 1365), p. 3. kcerber, 35 3C :‘j‘k; ~~HblstiCE 32 34Bird and De Wulf, p. 663 and De Wulf, passim. 35De Wulf, p. 48. 36Richard A. Musgrave. "Estimating the Distribution of the Tax Burden" Chapter 2 in Problems of Tax Administra- tion in Latin America: Papers and Proceedings of a Confer- ence held in Buenos Aires, Argentina, October, 1961 (Baltimore, 1965). P. 31. 37Thailand, Bank of Thailand, Monthly Bulletin, December, 1964, and December, 1970. 38De Wulf, p. 2. 39The two sources of data are (1) Thailand, National Statistical Office, Reports of the Household Expenditure Sur- vey, 1962-1963, 7 vols. (Bangkok, 1968); (2) Idem., Report of the Socio-Economic Survey, 1968-1969 (Bangkok, 1973). CHAPTER II THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME IN THAILAND: 1963 AND 1969 The object of a fiscal incidence study is the compu- tation of the effective rates of tax burdens and public ex- penditure benefits. To do so, an income base is needed as a denominator for the values of the taxburdens and expendi- ture benefits. It is obvious that the selection of an in- come base is very important; if an incorrect or inaccurate base is used, the pattern of fiscal incidence could be dis- torted. Therefore, a precondition for a successful fiscal incidence study is the determination of a proper income base for each income class. But the determination of an income base by size is not at all easy. It usually involves many conceptual dif- ficulties, such as a definition of income, the difference in income received at different periods, the selection of the individual or the family as a unit of analysis, and so on. In an underdeveloped country such as Thailand, the problem is even more serious; in addition to the familiar conceptual problems, the necessary statistical data often do not exist and if they do, they often are unreliable.1 33 :ibution 5 cf the inco :Lued as i uquns ltst econc: futons, who '1? the mar fl) th cha between the l J. 3381' WC 3. :et weal- 15' .. fo .- Inco: 119's econo: 13? to these q .2... _ C is): 0‘ none 34 Conceptual and Statistical Problems in Estimating Income Distribution The two major conceptual problems in an income dis- ‘tribution study are the concept of income and the selection Choosing what is to be in- Cm'the income recipient unit. Income can exist in Cluded as income is not always simple. lmany forms and may be differently defined in various settings. .Most;economists, however, prefer the definition of Henry C. Sinuons, who defined personal income as "the algebraic sum of (l) the market value of rights exercised in consumption, and (2) the change in the value of the stock of property rights between the beginning and the end of the period in question."2 Itrl other words, it is the sum of consumption plus the change j~rl net wealth. A similar definition was proposed by R. M. Income is "the money value of the net accretion to Eiéijxg: Accord- C>Il€e's economic power between two points in time." J‘IISJ to these definitions, income is more than the flow con- C:E31?t of money income; it also includes, among other things, 1*r1<}ome in kind, imputed rental income, corporate savings, t“Tansfers and gifts, and capital gains. In national income accounting, where terminology is rtIQII'—‘e or less standardized, aggregate income is defined as the payments, disbursed or accrued, to factors of production :tf<:,1: services rendered in a given period. Personal income in- <:=:LV\1des all payments which are actually disbursed to the fac- .t:<:’1=s of production plus various kinds of transfers, but cor- <:’1=ate savings are excluded because this kind of income is KCERd, r 25; rsone :stofte geriirg u; stnies, 1 hearaile imestigat H g. ‘ A ' {1.1.0.53}, J P: ~earninc ’: r- . " due 'wdl ::r m V ““6: 1 as a). “0351-1 13" 'r' ‘ ‘3lcua1 {7‘ .2..Sed On 4.. , “v.1" 35 accrued, not disbursed. Disposable income is that portion of personal income remaining when all personal taxes have Thus, in the area of income taxation, the con- been paid. cept of taxable income may be very narrow or very broad de- pending upon a nation's tax law. In income distribution Studies, the concepts used are not uniform but depend upon the availability of data and the aim or preference of the investigator. Assuming that the statistical data pose no Problem, if one wanted to measure the distribution of rewards for employment in different occupations, then income defined as earnings before taxes would be the most relevant concept. If one wanted to determine the relationship between the dis- tribution of income and earning abilities, then all types of c3Ompensation in money and in kind would be more appropriate. For other purposes, there are other income concepts. As noted earlier, in addition to the problem of choosing an appropriate income concept, there is the problem of selecting the income recipient unit. The choice of the individual as the unit of study is desirable if attention is chusedon the relationship between the distribution of pro- dllctive earnings and current output or the distribution of income and earning abilities. If the purpose is to examine the changes in consumption and saving as a result of certain E Qlicies, or to measure the changes in the "welfare" of the Q‘Ql'isumers, then the family. unit is more appropriate. How- Q\’er the type of unit may be determined by the availability 3 data. If income data are obtained from a population census, ‘ A far esti: 'flh‘ , ._.at 01:6 ('2 ‘ 36 then the recipient unit is likely to be the individual; of they are obtained from household surveys, the recipient unit is likely to be the family. It is possible, of course, to study both units if the data permit, but the outcome of the analysis would be different. A point referred to above was the statistical source The four data sources for estimating income distribution. (1) a population cen- most often used by researchers are: (3) results from sample surveys, Sus, (2) income tax returns, arui (4) composite sources based on national income data and Other related information . Let us first consider the population census. If the Census is complete, and if it contains information on the in- cOmes of individuals, it is probably the best data source for computing income distribution. But in many countries, EDEizrticularly the less-developed, population census data often Eilree incomplete and, as a rule, almost are devoid of the need- In such cases, the census would ea¢1_ information on income. C311£Ly be useful in providing information on the size of the EJ<:irpulation or the number of households. Income tax returns also could be used to compute the ciii~£3tribution of income of individuals, but these alone are jLJL"issufficient. In most countries the taxable income concept usually narrow and is likely to omit persons in the lower- 5L453 1L”‘3l<:ome brackets. Other income elements might escape measure- ‘Eilnt through such tax loopholes as exemptions, preferential tax tre evasior fore, 1 could i may 5 .K 1 #335.) which t Giten t The Pro 37 I tax treatment, and capital gains, not to mention the tax evasion which is pervasive in less-developed nations. There- fore, the taxable income base pep s3 is inadequate. Household sample surveys, the third source of data, could be household income surveys or household expenditure surveys including questions on family income. The personal income concept used could follow that of Simons and Haig as closely as one wished. The surveys also could be designed to illuminate the structure of the very poor or the very wealthy. What is most crucial, however, is the manner in which the survey is conducted, rather than its design. ()ften the surveying agency is constrained by a low budget, vihich results in too small a sample size, by limited man- Power, incompetent interviewing, and a lack of cooperation from the households. Nevertheless, the survey method is Still the most flexible. Finally, composite sources have no single origin. The process of compiling such information normally would be- Siin with finding the reference levels of national income 31>roken down into income from wages and salaries, self- Eamployed income, transfer payments, income from prOperty, and £30 on. Then the distribution of each of these separate cate- Syories would be estimated using information from other Siources. For example, the distribution of salaried income (:ould be estimated from industrial and business censuses or Ilabor surveys; self-employed income, in the case of most urban Inouseholds, from tax records, or for rural households from an agricultural registers. avoids the U the higher i satple surve :age, howeve incompatible iifficult. Prev ‘ H “(an ‘3'“ and undl 38 agricultural census; and transfer income from social security registers. The advantage of this type of data is that it avoids the underreporting of most income classes, especially the higher income brackets, which is a problem in household sample surveys and tax return data. Its greatest disadvan- tage, however, is that data from different sources may be incompatible and adjusting separate income groups is thus difficult.4 Previous income distribution studies in both devel- <5ped and underdeveloped countries most frequently have used 613 a single data source the household income and expenditure ssurvey. This survey alone may be used or it may be supple- nuanted by other sources, such as tax data, to confirm the Ebccuracy of the distribution of the top income groups. One Ineason for the popularity of this method may be that it is Ikelatively easier to gather information about income dis- t:ribution through surveys than through other collection ITlethods. Both the accuracy and reliability of the results Could be improved through better technical and administra- 't:ive management and increased budgets. True, the problem <2>f sampling error always is present, but its advantages are ESufficient to offset this drawback. Besides, sampling errors <::an be reduced through sound statistical design and execution ‘:>f this survey. tween 1962 a: werweflnnlv c A....C..ud£.--J s .,_. .311 SLEI'JE‘.’ ‘n ‘ Other .. "ng V a . “MES on till .- ‘6’. ....s will be ..I‘ A ‘ g ...9 2:80 1 O I‘ 39 In Thailand, there is no choice among alternatives: The only data available are from household surveys. As of 1974, four national household expenditure (and income) sur- veys had been conducted by the National Statistical Office The first was conducted during 1958, the second be- (NSO). the third during 1969, and the fourth tween 1962 and 1963, in 1971. Only the 1962-1963 and 1969 surveys were usable here; the 1958 survey was too small and was limited to a few nonrandomly selected municipal areas, and the results of the .1971 survey were not yet published. Other researchers have made estimates of or conducted These ef- Studies on the distribution of income in Thailand. and ftirts will be reviewed briefly, and their weaknesses time need for a new study will be discussed. Past Studies of Income Distribution in Thailand Until early 1973, only four scholars were seriously it'l‘volved in the study of income distribution in Thailand and Harry T. Oshima, had published their findings in some form. whose article was published in the October 1970 issue of EEEEge Malayan Economic Review, compared the sources of income 5 zidrrequality in Thailand with those of other Asian countries. 'Z\~J~though not an exhaustive examination, this study provid- ‘Ei'ii a penetrating insight into the relationship between in- QQtrne inequality and economic growth in Thailand. Udom Kerdphibule of Kasetsart University was probably jtllfile first Thai scholar to undertake an intensive study of the distribution tonic Connis ‘he income d sible for th in the 1971 1 later in Vol. Ed the Far 1 Effective prt K 1972.6 In D. Ether article :ission for ; Distribution Fiblished in Thaw Ker (1 1.1g efforts, 40 distribution of income in Thailand. As a member of an Eco- nomic Commission for Asia and the Far East organized to study the income distribution of the region in 1971, he was respon- sible for the report on Thailand. His work first appeared in the 1971 Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East, and later in Volume III of another Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East publication, Interregional Trade Prg'Lection, E_f :fective Protection, and Income Distribution, published in 19 72.6 In December of the same year, Kerdphibule wrote an- other article using the same material from the Economic Com- mission for Asia and the Far East entitled "Income and the Distribution of Income of the Agricultural Sector," it was Published in the Thai Journal of Agricultural Economics (in Kerdphibule should be much credited for his pioneer- Thai) .7 His ing efforts, but his work also had many deficiencies: a~11alysis, for the most part, was sketchy; certain methodolo- gies were questionable; and there were a few careless mistakes. Therefore, the conclusions reached, if not misleading, must be interpreted with caution. In August, 1972, William A. McCleary of Thammasat University published his study on income distribution in Thai- 1 and in a Thammasat University Discussion Paper. His empha- % is was not so much on income estimation and its adjustment 8 on the sources and magnitudes of income changes between 1 9 62-1963 and 1968-1969, using the existing income distribution Q C I ls‘l‘ies. His work was more or less an exten31on and expan31on Pi. As :5 income c' :creestima fily, by a :c:;letenes iiates wil “‘hn ‘ can. 46" ‘ an MC. ~38 Of E As H a: di;.rih 41 of Oshima's article, with an emphasis on Thailand. Finally, in an ongoing project, Oey Astra Meesook, also of Thammasat University, is attempting to give special attention to the consistency in the estimation process and to incorporate into the money income concept certain income adjusting elements, especially income in kind. When com- pleted, her findings will add substantially to the scant lit- erature on income distribution in Thailand.10 As there exists no systematic and adequate account of income distribution in Thailand, this study will attempt to reestimate income distribution in 1963 and 1969. Hope- fully, by avoiding previous pitfalls and by emphasizing the completeness and consistency of the estimates, these new es- ‘tinmtes will provide much improved income bases for the sub— sequent incidence study. Income Distribution in 1963 Pfliture of Data and Method of Study As mentioned earlier, the main source of data on in- CCHne distribution in 1963 is the 1962-1963 Household Expendi- t1ire Survey.11 The results were published in seven volumes, Orua for the whole country, one for the municipal sections of Bangkok and Thonburi, and one for each of the five regions: thenorth, northeast, central plain, east, and south. The survey further classified each region into towns and villages, with the exception of Bangkok and Thonburi, where only the 23.7.5 were su: are, first, 1 getterns of m rifle informat: ani services basis for calc Sample airatified sar 3;}:5 or dis .L _ 50‘ (I) U) ECOHd St: k :"“hu 1 krdur’ and tr ~‘Afi. "~29? .‘v 1 I Cl»‘l bl 32:3 Selected ”129: the } ":..~:S Was US I120 ‘f‘n '. '3 1.: “ but 3" L." er I \A‘ C k“ ‘w Q “HHQ + 50 E; ‘2. 42 towns were surveyed. The two main objectives of the survey, were, first, to study the income, expenditure, and savings patterns of noninstitutional households and, second, to pro- vide information on the relative importance of various goods and services in household spending patterns to be used as a basis for calculating a consumer price index. Sample households were selected by a three-stage Stratified sampling technique. The first stage selected the amphurs or districts from over 400 amphurs in the country, the second stage the city blocks or villages from the chosen amphur, and the third stage the final households from the Chosen city blocks and villages. At each stage, sample units Were selected systematically with probabilities proportional to size; the household information from the 1960 population C3ensus was used for this purpose. The total sample selected, 6 a 420 households, was divided into 2,310 households in towns and 4,120 households in villages. The unit of study was the economic family, defined either as a single person who was financially independent of other family groups or as a group of persons who lived and ate together, pooling their income and drawing from this com- mon fund to pay for food, housing and other living essentials. One or more of these families living together formed a "house- hgld." In other words, there could be more than one economic fanlily in a household, although almost all households were of the one-family type. Th CCZEI whic ‘r ‘1 FL, H (L) k 1; a) ’3 r+ 53:1". sourC mdbfoker assist me and the va Th iistributi tion of fa each locat it was ass the entire class was < weighing correspond: could be ft in each cle into corres Lat change "0115 give T: ‘54 t. LS tot 33‘s ’ ‘ 1“ thi 43 The income concept used was total family money in- come, which included wages and salaries, profits from self— employment or family enterprises, income from rent and from such sources as pensions and annuities, interest, dividend and brokerage fees, money received through public and private assistance, lottery prizes and net winnings from gambling, and the value of food received as pay. The general methodology used in estimating income distribution in 1963 was as follows: the frequency distribu- tion of families as recorded in different income classes in each location and each region was taken from the survey, and it was assumed that these families were representative of the entire country. After the mean or average income of each class was determined, the distribution of income was obtained by weighing the average income in each income class with the corresponding household share. This sample distribution could be further "blown up" by multiplying the average income in each class with the number of actual families classified into corresponding income classes. The multiplication would not change the pattern of income distribution; rather, it would give the level of the total income of the whole country. To this total (money) income, various adjustments would be made in this study to make it as complete as possible. The Income Distribution Estimates Two pertinent types of information concerning family income distribution were gathered in the 1962-1963 survey. First, the was obtain Second, th regions, e five incom 2.1 and 2. At of income c the average “0 Sets 0‘ l.‘ k ( ( :1 . (D J — 44 First, the frequency distribution of families in all regions was obtained and was classified into ten income classes. Second, the distribution of average monthly incomes for all regions, except Bangkok and Thonburi, was classified into five income classes. This information is presented in Tables 2.1 and 2.2. At first glance, it would seem that the distribution of income could be easily estimated simply by multiplying the average monthly income in Table 2.2 with the relevant corresponding percentage share of households in each income bracket in Table 2.1, after reducing the income classes in Table 2.1 from ten to five. In fact, the matter is not so simple because of the inconsistent use of the family income concept by the NSC. In the survey, both the annual and monthly income questions were asked separately, resulting in two sets of different income figures, both of which were pub- lished without adjustment. Whereas the families were classi- fied into annual income classes as in Table 2.1, the average monthly income for each of these classes was not obtained by converting the average annual income into the average monthly income; the latter figure was the one obtained directly from the questionnaires. In other words, the NSC used the annual income data to group the distribution of families, and then used the monthly income data from the survey responses to compute the average monthly income for each of these family classes as the average monthly income figure. As a result, Enigma UMBDHUCnxwrfl "£97993: MCTAINcmH 3:; SE; Trummnéu QZOCCH \nnu TAJANECL k0 :CfiUZQwMUQHQ .n.Kt...LCUUH._:|IN .N U~.~£~. 45 .3 d zooms £99.55 éooofix 323 “mooflumofl ago mfiufimea 328:8 mfi mo uuommm define HBUflpfim HEQsz 6539? "8.38 no mo ~.o do To o4 m4. o.~m fimm m.mm o.ooH 590m m.o m.o m.o m.o w.o o.m m.m m.h~ o.mm v.5m o.ooa Hmuucmo do do No I To m4 o.» TR mom oém o.ooH pmmm do .I ~.o do do m.o dm odd mow o.mo o.ooH 582 nu I do do do mo m4 mo «.2 mos o.ooH ummmfiuoz do do do do m.o «4 dm moa oém Tom o.ooH "moofldt, EH mA 54 dm o.m To dam oém mos no o.ooa £50m v.H m.o ¢.H N.m m.m m.v H.va N.Hv >.ma m.HH o.ooa Hmuucmo o.o ~.H o.~ m.m o.m m.o m.oa o.>m o.oH ~.mH o.ooH ammo dH o.o o4 o.o o4 m.m dos o.R odd «.2 o.ooH fiuoz o4 To o4 o.~ Em do 5.3 mdm Ema ooa o.ood $8532 «4 mo EH Tm 5m o.m 5.3 mom 5: TS o.ooH "938. mgr. ~.~ o.m oé m.m mos TS Tam o.mH oé o.ooa fiéncofi. uxflmfim o.o mo o.o To o4 Tm Em 93 mom doo o.ooH 283.9395 gone... 83% mod: moo.mm moo.o~ moo.mm mooga mamas oom.m ooo.m coo ooo.oo nooo.ov uooo.om uooo.om uoooJN uooo.oa nooo.~H uooo.o nooo.m H85 Ham Hanna exam: mommmanomsoocH 39389. mooaamofl mfi 58m mommmd QBBH 3 mmfigm mo Sflfiflhfio mmflfiafluudm 3nd. mm>nsm onsuflucmmxm Table 2.2--[ Income Clas (Baht) 46 Table 2.2--Distribution of Monthly Income by Annual Income Classes from Household Expenditure Survey, 1962-1963 (Amounts in Baht) Income Classes North Bangkok- (Baht) East North East Center South Thornburi Urban Areas Under 3,000 357 273 305 368 466 } 428 3,000 -. 5,999 491 428 585 490 653 6,000 - 11,999 794 802 792 769 766 756 12,000 - 17,999 1,341 1,339 1,359 1,375 1,222 } 2,470 18,000 and over 2,935 3,211 2,413 3,000 2,882 Average 1,089 834 1,055 1,090 1,206 1,519 Rural Areas Under 3,000 151 252 318 311 .334 -- 3,000 - 5,999 377 437 469 494 487 -- 6,000 - 11,999 704 639 850 916 858 -- 12,000 - 17,999 1,358 1,344 1,236 1,698 1,474 -- 18,000 and over 1,653 2,294 1,794 2,261 2,093 -- Average 249 378 612 718 619 -- Source: Adapted from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Reports of the Household Expenditure Survey, 1962-1963, 7 volumes. 3051; month] the two 10" 'jl'ZPed" ti which n0 96 whereas the iirectly fr As a result :cnthly inc limits, or classes whe :1 3418 . 47 most monthly average family incomes, particularly those in the two lower brackets, when converted into an annual figure, "jumped" the class limits into odd arrays of figures from which no general conclusion could be drawn. Furthermore, whereas the average monthly incomes of families were available directly from the survey, the average annual incomes were not. As a result, one is faced with the dilemma of accepting the monthly income figures, some of which would jump the class limits, or accepting the distribution of families by income classes where the annual income class means were not avail- able. Finally, although the survey obtained information on income in kind (or nonmoney income), the information was in- completely presented. Only the average monthly income in kind for each region as a whole was shown, not the average monthly income in kind broken down by income classes. This average nonmoney income figure thus proved of very little use for this study except perhaps as a check against a similar figure derived from other sources. In view of these deficiencies, a new approach for dealing with the existing data was necessary. After careful consideration, this study decided not to use the mean monthly income published in the survey reports (Table 2.2), but to ac- cept the distribution of families by annual income class (Table 2.1). Having so decided, the next task was to find ways of obtaining average annual incomes that were consistent 12 with the class limits. The estimating technique chosen is iescribed l 1. For all to: classes 33.1131 incc 2. As the regions, t) lose its me hculd be re ail the rec 3' F0r the ’s Lzahit 18 ' 00 is (.1) EC to fin. v. “‘9 method 1 V- a. u‘st ributior 48 described below: 1. For all classes in Table 2.1 except the top and the bot- tom classes, the class midpoints were used as the average annual income. 2. As the midpoints would be the same in each class for all regions, the analysis of income distribution by region would lose its meaning. In this case, only the national distribution would be relevant.13 Still the town-village or urban-rural data presentation would be retained because in most cases it was possible to have national figures only through summation of all the regional or locational estimates. 3. For the two open-ended classes, that is, the lowest in- come class (under Baht 3,000) and the highest income class (Baht 18,000 and over), three alternative methods could be used to find their midpoints, namely, the arbitrary method, the method based on information from other reliable income distribution data, and the method based on some mathematical functions, particularly the Pareto distribution function. These alternatives are discussed below: (a) The Arbitrary Method. In using this method, a re- searcher simply arbitrarily assigns the midpoint values to the top and the bottom open-ended brackets. Usually no rea- sons are given for why these values are selected; they nor- mally come from the subjective or intuitive judgment of the individual researcher. (b) informatiu compute t1 year in g tribution that the 1 brackets :? 1111969 ar C ) r—o. the bot next highe the corres average in tides that Vould be u: 49 (b) The Related Distribution Method. This method uses information from the income distribution in other years to compute the mean incomes to the open-ended brackets of the year in question. In the case of Thailand, the income dis- tribution data for 1969 could be adapted for 1963 assuming that the pattern of average income in the two open-ended brackets in relation to their adjacent brackets is the same in 1969 and 1963. The proportion of the 1969 average income of the bottom (top) bracket, which is known, to that of the next higher (next lower) bracket could be used to compute the corresponding mean incomes for 1963. For example, if the average income of the top income bracket in 1969 was four times that of its next lower bracket, then this proportion would be used to multiply the known midpoint of the second top bracket in 1963 to obtain the estimated midpoint of the top bracket for that year.14 This is certainly an improve- ment over the first method, because it is not unreasonable to assume that the average income of one bracket relative to that of the next bracket would be the same from year to year. Or, if there should be any changes, it is unlikely that they would be so great as to render this assumption totally unrealistic. (c) The Mathematical Function Method. This method is usually based on the Pareto function, which stipulates that the percentage of peOple with income higher than any given in- come level will fall at a constant rate as the income level 15 increases. In mathematical form, the function is given as: where N i Y higher the '53: persons which rep: cone recei 50 _ -b Ny — Ay , y 1 YO > 0, and b > 1, where Ny is the number of persons or families with income higher than the level y; Yo is the minimum income received by persons or families; A is the location or monetary unit parameter; and b is the Pareto coefficient or the parameter which represents the percentage change in the number of in- come receivers to the percentage change in the income level. If personal income is believed to be distributed according to this Pareto function, various information on in- come distribution could be derived from manipulating the func- tion. If the 1963 mean income of the bottom bracket were to be estimated using the Pareto function, the procedure would require, first, the estimation of the minimum income, Y and, or second, use of the midpoint between this income and the floor of the second bottom bracket as the mean income for the bot- tom bracket. For the mean income of the top bracket, the function would be used to estimate the total income attribut- able to this bracket. By dividing this total income by the total number of persons or families in the bracket, the mean income of the bracket would result.16 Although this method of estimating the mean incomes of the open-ended brackets is elegant and impartial, it has several drawbacks. First, that the Pareto coefficient is al- 17 Instead, the co— ways a constant, was empirically refuted. efficient was often found to vary across an income range. Therefore, to use a constant relationship between income 1 .; the 1 though i'come c “9 QiStri the 10m Igtal 51 recipients and the level of income to find the mean incomes of the open-ended brackets is quite unwarranted. Second, al- though the Pareto function fits the upper tail of the actual income distribution quite well, it does so poorly for the lower tail. As a result, the minimum income derived from the Pareto function would almost always overestimate the true dis- tribution. Third, the Pareto function is also known to have overestimated the mean income of the tOp bracket.18 Given these reservations concerning the Pareto method, and since the arbitrary method was inappropriate because the 1963 data should be on a comparable basis with the 1969 data (for the purpose of this study at least), the related dis- tribution method was chosen for use here. This meant that the distribution patterns of the 1969 data was employed to find the mean incomes for the two open-ended classes. When all the midpoints of the 1963 income classes were multiplied by the number of families of the respective income classes (see Appendix A), the results obtained were the total family money income classified by size of income. This money income is similar in concept to the personal income used in the national income accounts. From Table 2.3 it can be seen that the inequality of the distribution of income is quite striking. The families in the lowest income bracket constituting almost half of the total families receive less than 13 percent of the total family money income, whereas the families in the top income Table 2. 3-' Income Cla (Baht) Eider 3,0( 3,000 — 6,000 - 1 1L000 - 1 18.000 - 2 '003 and ‘111 Clds \ Wur\C9: CC Be a 52 Table 2.3--Distribution of Total Families and Total Family Money Income, by Income Classes, 1963 Mean Total Families Total Income Income Classes Income ‘Baht’ ”11322:?“ (Thousand> viii; 14913123..) iii; Under 3,000 1,800a 2,489.0 48.1C 4,480.1 13.0 3,000 - 5,999 4,500 1,074.0 20.8 4,832.9 14.0 6,000 - 11,999 9,000 1,010.9 19.5 9,098.4 26.4 12,000 — 17,999 15,000 300.8 5.8 4,511.7 13.1 18,000 - 23,999 21,000 126.0 2.4 2,646.0 7.7 24,000 - 29,999 27,000 50.6 1.0 1,366.3 4.0 30,000 - 35,999 33,000 37.5 0.7 1,238.6 3.6 36,000 - 47,999 42,000 33.6 0.6 1,412.1 4.1 48,000 - 59,999 54,000 18.3 0.4 987.1 2.9 60,000 and over 117,500a 33.4 0.6 3,918.0 11.4 All Classes 6,666b 5,174.1 100.0 34,491.2 100.00 Source: Computed from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Reports of the Household Expenditure Survey, 1962- 1963, (Bangkok, 1966), 7 volumes. aFor the calculation of midpoints of the two Open- ended brackets, see text. bThis figure is the average annual family income for the whole country. cSlightly different from the original percentage of 48.4 due to rounding errors in computation. bracket c1 all famil. income. 1' discussed fiature o f R 1968-1969.‘ was Sdbstar a; ‘h ~‘- uOUSEhQ] Survey .I hon. .1; 1n Prev 53 bracket comprising less than two-thirds of one percent of all families receive almost 12 percent of the total family income. A more exact measure of income inequality will be discussed later in this chapter. Income Distribution in 1969 Nature of Data and Method of Study Similar to the situation in 1963, the main source of data for estimating income distribution in 1969 also came from a household sample survey, the socio-economic survey of 1968-1969.19 The objective of this and the 1962-1963 survey was substantially the same, that is, to study the composition of households and their spending patterns. The 1968-1969 survey, however, emphasized an important aspect which was lack- ing in previous surveys: explicitly to obtain information on household income, sources of income, and distribution of 20 As a result, income both in municipal areas and villages. the 1968-1969 survey provides much more complete, consistent, and reliable information on the distribution of income in Thailand than any other source. Although there are many de- fects in the data, the quality is much improved over the 1962-1963 material. The survey procedure was detailed in a single volume, Report of the Socio—Economic Survey, 1968/69, published by the National Statistical Office in 1974. Sample households were again selected by a three-stage stratified sampling technique. 1962-1963. Thorburi w :hangwads schregions villages t; The third 1 3! sample 1 from each c_ its to £01.11 1'5“) Units January an ‘ zen-ts in th £530 hQ‘dSe . “§ Vs s ‘1 (C u srom 6,0 ‘ - “170%- sauents) The ,..3 who 1 i“ 'v Nir' alti ritmy 5‘ . Stl a she 196 ”scenes the ‘\ sg 1. “Q ‘569 54 technique, which was somewhat different from that used in 1962-1963. In the first stage, in addition to Bangkok and Thonburi which were selected as self-representative, two changwads or provinces were selected from each of the nine subregions of the country. Sample city blocks and sample villages then were selected at random from each changwad. The third stage classified households in each sample block or sample village into different occupational groups, and from each group at least two households were selected at ran- dom to form the final sample households. Interviews with the 1,500 units selected were carried out in three rounds between January and September 1969, with partial household replace- ments in the second and third rounds. In all, approximately 4,500 households were canvassed in each round. At the end of the survey period, some 13,500 questionnaires were obtain- ed from 6,000 sample households (the original number plus re- placements). The unit of study in this survey was the household, defined as a person or a group of related or unrelated per- sons who live, eat, and share other living essentials to- gether, although some persons may keep their finances sepa- rately. Strictly speaking, this is not the same unit study in the 1962-1963 survey, which used the economic family. But because the majority of households in Thailand are one-family households. the difference is unimportant; the household in the 1969 survey can be considered identical to the economic that used overtime 1 snares of received 1 attention 1'1 the ea r 55 family of the 1962-1963 survey.21 The 1968-1969 survey's income concept is the same as that used in earlier projects. It includes wages, salaries, overtime payments, bonuses, net profits from self—employment, shares of profit and interest, pensions and annuities, money received for rents, and income from other sources. One other difference between the two surveys deserves attention here: the composition of urban and rural areas. In the earlier survey, both municipalities and sanitary dis- tricts were both classified as urban areas (or towns), where- as the villages outside municipal or sanitary districts were regarded as rural areas. In the 1968-1969 survey, only the municipalities were designated as urban areas, and both sani- tary districts and villages were combined as rural areas. The main reason for this reclassification, according to an NSO official, was that the sanitary districts in 1969 exhibit- ed characteristics more closely resembling villages than mu— nicipalities, hence the change. This could also mean that the municipalities had become much more "urbanized" in the intervening six years, much more so than the sanitary districts. The discrepancy, however, should not have any effect on the analysis in this study, especially since the main emphasis is at the national, not the locational or regional level. The general methodology for estimating the national distribution of income in 1969 was similar to that used in 1963. The income distribution pattern determined by the sur- Vey was considered representative of all households in the gantry: 5 Cf househc lers are e ;resentati survey rep used, and given. MO. ended inco: are also a: ;olate sucl fit. NOE 3lever A urban and r 56 country, and the figure was "blown up" by the distribution of households by corresponding income classes.22 Fewer prob- lems are encountered in the 1969 than in the 1963 data. The presentation of household distribution of income in the 1969 survey report is consistent: the annual income classes are used, and the average annual income for each income class is given. Moreover, the actual average incomes for both open- ended income classes--the top and the bottom income brackets-- are also available, thus eliminating risky attempts to inter- polate such mean incomes. The Income Distribution Estimates Most information needed for estimating income distri- bution appears in the ten published tables in the 1968-1969 survey report. The data are presented in a rather odd way, however, Although the income distribution is given for both urban and rural areas in all of the four geographical regions (the previously separated center and east are combined into one region), the national income distribution is omitted. Although one could combine the total families and incomes of urban and rural areas to arrive at this figure, this process is not easy because the income class intervals for urban and rural households are different. .Within each urban area, the income level is divided into 12 brackets, ranging from under Baht 3,000 per year to over Baht 60,000 per year. Within each rural area, the income level begins with the same lower income br incore br ed in the should be TL- Avg mayas' rut Seated in 3111 that i; “V93 a: e an: 57 bracket, but then progresses by smaller intervals until the top, open-ended eleventh bracket of Baht 33,000 and over is reached. To obtain a national income distribution, the urban income brackets must be compressed to coincide with the rural income brackets. As a result, only seven brackets are obtain- ed in the national income distribution.{ There is no system- atic way short of retabulation of the entire survey data to expand the income brackets of the rural households to fit the wider urban income brackets. This is a serious fault which should be corrected in the next survey. The distribution of households and income for urban areas, rural areas, and the entire country for 1969 are pre- sented in Tables 2.4, 2.5, and 2.6 respectively. Before discussing these tables, it should be pointed out that in estimating these income distribution series, the average annual income by income classes used is not that pub- lished in the NSC report. Rather, the figures were supplied by Dr. Oey Meesook of Thammasat University. (See Appendix B for details.) Sensing that there might be some inconsist- encies in the final tabulation of results, Dr. Meesook ob- tained the original survey tapes and ran them through the computer to check the reliability of the official results. She found that, indeed, some adjustments were made in the final tabulations, especially in the two open-ended brackets.23 The average income of the bottom bracket in the N80 series was generally larger than Meesook's recomputed figure, and H Income (85 Under 3 3,000 6,000 9,000- 12,000 . 15,000 . 18.000 - 24,000 - 30.000 - 36.000 - 49.000 - 60.000 a All C1 58 Table 2.4--Distribution of Money Income of Urban Households, by Income Classes, 1969 Average Income Classes Annual Total Total (Baht) Income Families Income (Baht) (Thousand) (Baht Million) Under 3,000 1,731 6.9 12.0 3,000 - 5,999 4,421 29.6 131.1 6,000 - 8,999 7,373 55.9 412.3 9,000 - 11,999 10,281 84.0 863.9 12,000 - 14,999 13,171 85.9 1,131.3 15,000 - 17,999 16,167 74.7 1,207.2 18,000 - 23,999 20,232 139.6 2,824.0 24,000 - 29,999 26,062 83.8 2,184.2 30,000 - 35,999 32,233 51.1 1,647.4 36,000 - 47,999 40,575 54.9 2,225.5 48,000 - 59,999 52,752 34.0 1,791.6 60,000 and over 116,742 61.7 7,201.5 All Classes 28,385a 762.1 21,632.0 Sources: Computed from retabulated results of the 1968-1969 Socio-Economic survey supplied by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University, and from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Report of the Popula- tion and Housing Censds, 1970, (Bangkok , 1974). aThis figure is the average annual money income for the whole urban households. Table 2 Income (Ba 1‘ U3 Jrh \es: 59 Table 2.5-—Distribution of Money Income of Rural Households, by Income Classes, 1969 Average Income Classes Annual Total Total (Baht) Income Families Income (Baht) (Thousand) (Baht Million) Under 3,000 3 1,701 1,416.6 2,409.1 3,000 - 4,499 3,629 797.7 2,894.9 4,500 - 5,999 5,128 579.0 2,969.4 6,000 - 7,499 6,591 505.8 3,334.0 7,500 - 8,999 8,141 384.9 3,133.4 9,000 - 10,499 9,624 325.7 3,134.4 10,500 - 11,999 11,130 177.0 1,969.7 12,000 - 14,999 13,113 312.8 4,101.8 15,000 - 17,999 16,009 197.9 3,168.7 18,000 - 32,999 23,002 334.7 7,699.4 33,000 and over 70,255 114.2 8,205.1 All Classes 8,359a 5,146.4 43,020.0 Sources: Computed from retabulated results of the 1968-1969 Socio-Economic survey supplied by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University, and from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Report of the Egpula- tion and Housing Census, 1970, (Bangkok, 1974). aThis figure is the average annual money income for the whole rural households. Table 2. (1 Income C a" o C) O l 60 Table 2.6--Distribution of Money Income of National House- holds, by Income Classes, 1969 Average Total Families Total Income Income Classes Annual (3..., £332? (8......) 2:3; M8123... 2:3; Under 3,000 1,701 1,423.5 24.1 2,421.0 3.7 3,000 - 5,999 4,263 1,406.4 23.8 5,995.4 9.3 6,000 - 8,999 7,268 946.6 16.0 6,879.8 10.6 9,000 - 11,999 10,172 586.7 9.9 5,968.0 9.2 12,000 - 14,999 13,125 398.7 6.8 5,233.1 8.1 15,000 - 17,999 16,052 272.6 4.6 4,375.9 6.8 18,000 and over 38,650 874.0 14.8 33,778.7 52.3 All Classes 10,942a 5,908.5 100.0 64,652.0 100.0 Sources: Computed from retabulated results of the 1968-1969 Socio-Economic survey supplied by Dr. Oey Astra _ Meesook of Thammasat University, and from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Report of the POpula- tion and Housing Census, 1970, (Bangkok, 1974). aThis figure is the average annual money income for the whole national households. that in other di were min come dis tile meflia: 61 that in the top bracket smaller. Apart from this, there were other differences in the average income levels, but these were minor and would not affect the general pattern of in- come distribution. The distributions of income in both urban and rural areas, as shown in Tables 2.4 and 2.5, are quite skewed. The mean income is Baht 28,385 for urban households and Baht 8,359 for rural households, but the median income is esti- mated at only Baht 19,890 and Baht 5,696 for these house- holds, respectively. This skewness also is reflected in the national figure, where the mean income is Baht 10,942 and the median income is estimated at Baht 6,395. In the national distribution of income series shown in Table 2.6, over one- half of the total families, bunching into the first two lower brackets, received only less than 4 percent of the total money income, whereas less than 15 percent of the total fami- lies comprising the top income bracket receive over one-half of the total money income. Again, a more concise measure of this apparent income inequality will be dealt with shortly. Comparison between the 1963 and 1969 Distributions of Income In comparing the distribution of income between the two years, one must always keep in mind the definitional and procedural differences between the two estimates pointed out earlier, particularly the difference in the classification of urban and rural households. At the national level, however, there ar In the f< rributior cal measr Income Di 19363 and 2.3 and 2 lies had a 62 there are few difficulties in comparing the two estimates. In the following section, the two estimates of income dis- tribution by income class will be compared, and the statisti- cal measurement of income inequality will be discussed. Income Distribution by Income Classes 1963 and 1969 Table 2.7, which compares the estimates of income distribution in 1963 and 1969, is taken partially from Tables 2.3 and 2.6. In 1963, an estimated 48.1 percent of all fami- lies had an annual money income of less than Baht 3,000 per family. This figure dropped to 24.1 percent in 1969. The fact that many families moved up the income scale by 1969 also is reflected in the percentage of families in the top income bracket: the figure increased from 5.6 percent in 1963 to 14.8 percent in 1969. However, one must be aware that this was in part attributable to about 15 percent in- crease in the price level from 1963 to 1969. In both years, families in the top bracket, as a group, received the largest share of total money income compared to any group below it, regardless of size. ~ To facilitate comparison of two or more distribution patterns, researchers often resort to the graphical technique of the Lorenz curve, introduced by M. O. Lorenz in 1905.24 In this case, this method requires that the cumulative dis- tribution of families be plotted along the bottom horizon- tal axis of a unit square as well as the cumulative percent- age distribution of income along the vertical axis on the left. A curve connecting all the points which correspond to .4J1C kt‘ LEC..~_ :2 C.— CECCE~ J». IFMZCSr Cw mlflzgfii trainegb 1.; CF: .moma ECG mwma a: mECUCH \fucg 130.4 xlnlflllrllll #62 NO CCfiuDQflhumwQ SUDEQQ Cmvmflgnunv Quinn .N QNQQE 63 .0.N can. m.~ $.38. 88w Eng 8058 0.00H 0.00..” 0.00H 0.03 0.30.00 m.000.m «400.3. H65...“ mommmHU H2 m.~m 0.3 m.mm 0.m 5.2.5.3 0.3.0 H.009: «dam 5.6 98 000.0." 0.0 0.0 060m; 0&5. 000.5 I 000.3 imam 0.m A “.43."; 0.00m A .70 0.0 H.mm~.m 5.0% 000.3” I 000.~.n «.0 0.0 0.000;.“ Womm 000?: I 000.0 0.0NA mdafi 0.000.0A 0.08:: 0.0a 0.3 0.03.0 0.03 000.0 I 000.0 m6 0.m~ 0.3 0.0m 0.30:.“ 0.0004 0.~mm.v 0.3.04 000:.“ I 000.m 5m .73 0.mH adv 0.HN¢.~ m.m~¢.a H.000; 0.mmv.m 000.0 “8.95 8.85 mmwagm 9505 mowadfim 9.85 83gb 9805 «mags—mm 35m: 003 M03 003 $3 mommmau NEH 8.0350me 9505 3an «o 20332 5 859a 628st fl 83255 @838 mg .3 :32 can 83 5 QaQH $82 Habflmz mo Sflaflfima 89.9mm somflmefio «lbw flame the coorc the Lore: tion of a both 1963 the two I. the line . :30th ale; 05 familie cllrve that PC‘Uld {near the dista: Clcser to 31119.): Lore pagein th. ¥Q$v v “ween the 64 the coordinates of these two cumulative frequencies is called the Lorenz curve. This curve represents the income distribu- tion of a given group of families.25 Using this technique, both 1963 and 1969 income distribution series are shown by the two Lorenz curves in Figure 2.1. In Figure 2.1, the straight diagonal line is called the line of perfect equality, or egalitarian line, since any point along this line would correspond to the same percentage of families having the same percentage of income. A Lorenz curve that traced a distribution pattern away from this line would mean that the distribution is more unequal the greater the distance. With two or more Lorenz curves, the one lying closer to the line of perfect equality and not crossing any other Lorenz curves would depict a more equal distributional pattern than the curve lying farther away. The similarity between the Lorenz curves of 1963 and 1969 in Figure 2.1 is quite extraordinary; they are virtually identical. Perhaps the 1969 income distribution could be seen to be very slightly more equal since its Lorenz curve lies closer to the egali- tarian line than the 1963 Lorenz curve around the fourth quin- tile of the household distribution. Visually, these two curves still lie quite far away from the line of perfect equal- ity, indicating that the money income distributions in both years are still quite unequal. A more precise measure of in- come inequality is considered in the next section. God 00 ’ 00 .‘OUCH .HO in I>dOCH3§U ON .lIb Finite 2 65 o 3 01963 . .5627 8I 0 3 0° C‘O H ~6’ R O > .4 753. 5 0 0L N O 20 “O 60 80 100 Cumulative % of Families Figure 2.1--Diatribution of Honey Incone in Thailand: 1963 and 1969 Statisti _____,__ to the e measure Furtherrn 91‘ : "'ereJ-Ore P L 66 Statistical Measures of Income Inequality While the Lorenz curve is a useful device for describ- ing the pattern of income distribution and depicting the ex- tent of its inequality according to the proximity of the curve to the egalitarian line, it is not a convenient practical measure of income inequality because of its graphical nature. Furthermore, in comparing two Lorenz curves, if one curve is not completely inside the other curve, but crosses it at some points, visual examination alone is inadequate or even impos- sible in determining which distribution is the more equal. Therefore, some measures or indices of income inequality are necessary. I There are more than a dozen income inequality measures from which to choose. Among these are the Pareto coefficient, the Gini concentration ratio, the coefficient of variation, the standard deviation of the logarithms of income, the rela— tive mean difference, the Elteto-Frigyes index, Atkinson's measure, Oshima's index of decile inequality, Theil's index, and so on.26 One of the most widely used measures, however, is the Gini concentration ratio or Gini coefficient, first developed by C. Gini in 1905.27 This ratio is superior to many other measures, but not necessarily the best, for as D. G. Champernowne has argued, there is no single "best" index or coefficient for every aspect of income inequality.28 The Gini concentration ratio has been widely adopted because it is easy to estimate from existing income distribution data, and the meaning of the coefficient itself is easy to = 67 understand. Moreover, it is directly associated with the con- cept of the Lorenz curve, which is widely used, making it an even more attractive measure. Using the Lorenz diagram as a reference, the Gini con- centration ratio measures the proportion of the area bounded by the egalitarian line and the Lorenz curve to the total area under the egalitarian line. The ratio ranges in value from zero (perfect equality) to one (perfect inequality). In the former case, the Lorenz curve will coincide with the egali- tarian line so that there is no bounded area. In the latter case, the Lorenz curve will trace the lower horizontal axis and the right vertical axis of the unit square, making the bounded area and the total area identical, so the ratio is one. Numerically, the Gini concentration ratio can be calcu- lated from the following formula: n _ _. l .. - G “ l 2 [i “1 fi-l) (Vi-1) + “£1 fi-l) (Yi yi-l)] ' where G is the Gini concentration ratio; fi and y1 are the ith observations of the cumulative fraction of the recipients or families and the cumulative fraction of income, respectively; and i = l,2,.......,n, where the nth observation is the final point in the Lorenz curve. This formula seems a cumbersome expression of a very simple idea, but the computation is straightforward and simple, although tedious. However, the above formula shows only an approximation of the area between the Lorenz curve and the egalitarian line, which tends to understate the actual inequality; when a straight line is curve. the SHIT. {1.1) 01 the Lore the Gini approxirr. 5:34 the integrati area unde :HRCtion L#336112 Cu 68 line is drawn between two observation points on the Lorenz curve, this line will lie above the actual Lorenz curve. So, the sum of all trapezoidal areas from point (0,0) to point (1.1) of the Lorenz box will be greater than the integral of the Lorenz curve between the same interval. Subsequently, the Gini ratio of concentration derived from this trapezoidal approximation (TA) method will be smaller than that derived from the integration method. If possible, the TA method should be replaced by the integration method, but to be able to integrate the entire area under the Lorenz curve, one must know the mathematical function of that curve. There are several ways in which the Lorenz curve function can be generated, but the method adopted in this study is the one devised by N. C. Kakwani and N. Podder of the World Bank.29 According to Kakwani and Podder, if F(x) is the pro- portion of units (families) that receive income up to x, and F1 (x) is the proportion of total income received by the same units, the Lorenz curve is then the graphical representation of the relationship between F(x) and F (x). This curve is 1 shown again in Figure 2.2. Supposing that P is any point on the curve with co- ordinates (F,Fl), the line from this point perpendicular to the egalitarian linelcalled n, would have the length l/JE (F-Fl), and the segment of the egalitarian line from the origin to n, called fl, would have the length l/fE (F+Fl). The equation of the Lorenz curve in terms of fl and n could now be written as: 69 P(F,F1) Figure 2.2-4 Hypothetical Loren: Curve where the c1 where tion, ’D n U) ‘ {~- tight: Estita .3. Q:+QY~H' "'c '5‘ CM ‘u MCi) f. 70 n = f(fl). (l) whereilvaries from zero to J3. Specifically,the equation of the curve proposed by Kakwani and Podder is of the form n = afia (J3 — fl§, a >o, a > o, and B > o, (2) where a, a, and B are the parameters to be estimated. From grouped observations of a given income distribu- tion, it is possible to obtain r and yt as the consistent t estimators of fit and nt, reSpectively, where = P + q rt t t {E and = P ‘ q Yt t t, «[3 where pt and qt are the observed cumulative proportions of income receiving units and the observed cumulative proportion of the total income of those units, respectively. The para- meters of the chosen Lorenz curve function (2) can then be estimated from the following log-transformed linear regres- sion equation: log yt = a + a log r + 8 log ( J3 - rt) + wlt’ (3) t where a = log a, and wlt = random disturbance. When the parameters are known and the Lorenz curve determined, the Gini concentration ratio can be estimated from the following integral: .5 G = 2 (I) f(‘fl) d1}, which for the Lorenz curve of Equation (2) is 9\ C!» A .t t A V b ‘\ ta A x. A: a! ‘ phd M. 71 f2- G=2éafia(\/_2--fl53 an 2a< (3)1” +8 B(l+0L, 1+8), where B(l+a, 1+8) is the Beta function, whose value could be obtained from the Beta function table or could be recomputed. Of course, the parameter fl is to be replaced in actual computation by p. As expected, the Gini concentration ratio obtained from the Kakwani-Podder (KP) method shows a greater degree of income inequality than the estimate from the TA method. Some may question the advantage of using the compli- cated KP method over the simple TA method in computing the Gini concentration ratios, especially when the income distri- bution observations are as few as five to seven, as in the case of Thailand in 1963 and 1969. It might appear that the new estimate is not worth the effort. Since the estimated Lorenz curves for both years have an extremely high goodness of fit and very low standard errors despite few observa- tions, and since the estimation procedure is greatly facili- tated by high-speed computers, there is good reason to se- lect the KP method in computing the Gini concentration ratios. What is more important is that the KP method makes the com- parison of the Gini concentration ratios between 1963 and 1969 much more compatible and more reliable because the prob- lem of having to approximate and then compare the ratios from two different observations with different frequency distribu- tions of households in the same income class is eliminated.30 that p somewh. from l< in Fig centrat 1963 an these 17: 0f inco; 72 At the end of the previous section it was mentioned that perhaps the 1969 money income distribution might be somewhat more equal than the same distribution in 1963 simply from looking at the free-hand drawing of the Lorenz curves in Figure 2.1. This belief is confirmed when the Gini con- centration ratios have been estimated at .5627 and .5550 for 1963 and 1969, respectively. Also, the Gini coefficients of these magnitudes are regarded as depicting a very high degree of income inequality in the country.31 Adjustments in the Income Concept An important question arises: How complete and re- liable is the estimate of money income distribution presented above? An honest answer would be that it is not as complete and reliable as one would wish. Certainly, it could not be compared to the well-known income concept used by Joseph Pechman and Benjamin Okner in their tax incidence study in the United States,32 and there is room for improvement. It is appropriate that the income concept of Pechman and Okner should serve as a model which this study strives to emulate. After careful investigation, it was found that various adjustments could be made to the Thai money income estimate to arrive at the equivalent of "adjusted family in- come" which Pechman and Okner used as the final income base in their tax incidence estimation. In this study, a similar income concept will be referred to simply as "adjusted in- come" in contrast to the previously obtained "money income." This adju (2) nonmo tained ea this inco nition of statistic jUStment I timates f Character naticmal tia'flates f to be tak in this s PErSOnal income es S6v966.5 73 This adjusted income will be composed of (1) personal income, (2) nonmoney income or income in kind, (3) net corporate re- tained earnings, and (4) indirect taxes.33 When completed, this income concept will be as close to the Simons-Haig defi- nition of income as one possibly could be under the present statistical conditions. In the following sections, the ad- justment procedures will be discussed in some detail. Personal Income It was pointed out earlier that the money income es- timates from the 1962-1963 and 1968-1969 surveys had the characteristics of personal income as defined in terms of national income accounting. But if the personal income es- timates from the national income accounts of Thailand were to be taken as reliable references, the money income estimate in this study would, to a great extent, understate the true personal income of households. In 1963 and 1969, personal income estimates from the national income accounts were Baht 56,966.S million and Baht 102,615.0 million, respectively.34 The money income in the same period was estimated in this study at Baht 34,491.2 million and Baht 64,652.0 million leaving the underreported personal income of Baht 22,475.3 million in 1963 and Baht 37,963.0 million in 1969. This is quite understandable and in fact to be expected because in- come information obtained from surveys is often incomplete due to the forgetfulness or the attempt to cover up actual income on the part of. the individuals being interviewed. The next imp< ed income this incc 90 percer group wou group . 31 taing , th 30719 POsi1 74 next important question is how to deal with this underreport- ed income. First, it was arbitrarily decided that 10 percent of this income be allocated to the top income bracket alone and 90 percent to all income brackets according to the pattern of the distribution of money income in each year. One might ask whether the extra 10 percent allotted to the highest income group would over—estimate the actual income position of that group. Most likely the answer would be negative. If any- thing, this figure is even insufficient to cover the real in- come position of the top income group since individuals in this group are likely to receive their income from various sources, some of which might not be accounted for at all. At any rate, this percentage was chosen because it would give a reasonable bias toward a more logical distribution of in- come. The distribution of this underreported personal income in absolute terms is presented in column 2 of Tables 2.8 and 2.9. The already determined money income plus underreported income should be equal to the personal income estimate of the national income account. However, further adjustments are needed owing to the apparent underestimation of the imputed rents of the owner-occupied homeowners given in the official statistics. In the national income accounts,both actual and im- puted rents of households were presented under the industrial category of "Ownership of Dwelling" in the gross national product ta hm census census, re} each month rent class mnunted tc Baht 175 a merage rem rural avera holders are reported as houses in t] d’w‘Ellings a] Mar-0cm“ Gillivalent i We of 170118 tainly Can 13 with f .01‘ Urban ho 75 product table. However, the recent 1970 population and hous- ing census casts serious doubt on these estimates.35 In that census, renters were asked about the actual rents they paid each month, and the frequency distribution of the renters by rent class was recorded. The average rent paid by a renter amounted to about Baht 263 a month for an urban dwelling, and 36 While the urban Baht 175 a month for a rural dwelling. average rent was credible and indeed quite acceptable, the rural average rent was not; it was too high. Most rural house- holders are farmers who own their own homes. Those who were reported as rural renters in the census are likely to rent houses in the sanitary districts or village centers, where dwellings are more similar to urban rented houses than rural owner-occupied homes. If one assumes that the actual rent is equivalent in value to the imputed rent regarding the same type of house, then the urban rent figure from the census cer- tainly can be used, but not the rural rent figure. With the above assumption, the total imputed rents for urban households would be Baht 1,470.2 million per year, compared with the official figure of only Baht 934.9 million. Total rents, actual and imputed, for urban households alone would be Baht 2,405.1 million, or 93 percent of the total value added for ownership of dwellings for the whole country given by the national accounts in 1969. In short, one is faced with a choice of accepting the estimates of the national ac- counts, which is likely to understate the actual rental income, or accepting the rent figure computed from average urban rent from the 1970 obviously is In so be one-fourt‘r per month or occupied rura Puted rents 3,876.9 mill the figure f S’lbtracting the amount , The tents to Va 5110Cation dCCoIding 1 76 from the 1970 population and housing census. The latter choice obviously is preferred. In so doing, the average rural rent is then assumed to be one-fourth the amount of the urban rent, or about Baht 65 per month or Baht 730 per year. With the total owner- occupied rural houses numbering 4,970,356, the estimated im- puted rents for rural households for 1969 would amount to Baht 3,876.9 million. Together with the total urban imputed rents, the figure for the whole country becomes Baht 5,347.1 million. Subtracting the official total rent of Baht 2,570.0 million, the amount of understated rent would be Baht 2,769.1 million. The next question is how to allocate these imputed rents to various income brackets. There appears no better allocation rule than to assume that such rents are distributed according to the distribution of income patterns in urban and rural areas, the reason being that the income positions of the owners, to a great extent, determines the quality (and value) of the houses they own. Lack of data in 1963 forced an assumption that the rent pattern was the same in 1963 as in 1969, but the level of average rents was deflated 15 percent, to about Baht 224 per month for an urban house and Baht 55 per month for a rural house. The proportions of rented to owned houses in both urban and rural areas also was assumed to be the same, that is, about 67 percent of urban families owned their own homes, while about 97 percent of rural families were owners. The number of owner-occupied houses in 1963 was estimated at 346,945 3‘“ tively' M rents! the for urban Z holdS- Th 2,700.4 mi same way a is Shotw'n i} The cannot be 0' the majoritj part of the produced for care in kind the lower in some in kind 77 546,945 and 4,036,170 in the urban and rural areas, respec- tively. Multiplying these figures by the average imputed rents, the total imputed rents become Baht 1,824.6 million for urban households and Baht 2,663.9 million for rural house- holds. The underreported rent, which was estimated at Baht 2,700.4 million, was then distributed to households in the same way as was done in 1969. The result of the distribution is shown in column 3 in Tables 2.8 and 2.9. Income in Kind The importance of income in kind in an income base cannot be overemphasized. In underdeveloped countries, where the majority of households are in the farming sector, a major part of their income is often in the form of food grown or produced for their own consumption. By including this "in- come in kind" in the income concept, the income positions of the lower income brackets are considerably improved. But in- come in kind is not necessarily restricted to the lower in- come groups; the higher groups could also receive income in kind in the form of fringe benefits, living amenities, stock options, real estate appreciation, and so forth. There is no published information available at present on income in kind distributed by income classes. Fortunately, the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey did include a question about the goods and services that were produced at home or were received free. Although the responses to this question were not reported in the published statistics, they could be ob- tained from the original data tapes. Again, Dr. Oey Astra Meesook wa tion from tinated va ceived fre C. Total her of hou for 1969 i: The Ageneral I total" incc Onthe 1969 tEChni 911e, 78 Meesook was instrumental in extracting this important informa- tion from the raw data. The average income in kind or the es- timated value of goods and services produced at home or re- ceived free by families by income classes is shown in Appendix C. Total income in kind is estimated by multiplying the num- ber of households by the average income in kind. The result for 1969 is shown in column 4 of Table 2.8. These 1969 data can be applied to the 1963 situation. A general methodology requires that (1) some relationship be- tween money income and income in kind in 1969 be established, and (2), by assuming that the same money income/income in kind relationship also existed in 1963, some adjusting factors which reflect this relationship be applied to the money income in 1963 to arrive at the income in kind for that year. Spe- cifically, the method used by Meesook was to regress the 1969 "total" income, defined as money income plus income in kind, on the 1969 money income using the least-square regression technique. The regression equation took the following form: yt = a + me + u, where Yt and Ym are the average total income and the average money income of households, respectively, a and b are estimat- ing parameters, and u is the stochastic disturbance. The re- gression is carried out for each urban and rural area in each region, and the results obtained are series of statistical estimates of average total income in each area in each region as a function of the average money income in that area and region (See Appendix C). F0 for 1963 i total inco tracting t total inc01 classified tain a nat: weights are income in k in column 4 One i395 should real as wel: Shares in C< with the Sir. in the Chap: Portant, I. hiS'her incop tangy in bu: Sec ' duty ma StatistiCal of T181; COrv until atte» H'v has are S‘ 79 For each linear estimate the average money income for 1963 is then plugged in to give the estimated average total income for a particular area and region. Simply by sub- tracting the average money income from the estimated average total income, what remains is the estimated income in kind classified by size, location, and region for 1963. To ob- tain a national income-in-kind figure, some distributive weights are applied to the above results. The 1963 average income in kind by income class for the whole country is shown in column 4 of Table 2.9. Net Corporate Retained Earnings One of the reasons that net corporate retained earn- ings should be included as income is that they constitute real as well as potential consumption power of those who hold shares in corporations. This reasoning is also consistent with the Simons-Haig definition of income mentioned earlier in the chapter. This portion of income has become quite im- portant. In Thailand, a growing number_of people in the higher income classes have begun to invest their surplus money in business corporations, as is evidenced by a tremen- dous expansion of private and public companies and increased security market activities during the past decade. But the statistical information on the net savings of corporations in Thailand is still very imperfect, and the available record of net corporate savings is certainly too low. Nevertheless, until attempts to gauge the true extent of net corporate sav- ings are successful, one must be content with the existing data. The the national profits afte ifllion, Bah zen enterpr efprivate Cc ntretained Such Baht ll tions and Bat tions and coc Ideal Wild be the C'iasses. Thi inThailand, 53m. were us 1- Savi Tota (a) (b) 80 data. The source of data for corporate saving is found in the national income accounts.37 In 1963 the net corporate profits after taxes and dividends were estimated at Baht 819.7 million, Baht 551.1 million of which were savings of govern- ment enterprises and Baht 264.6 million of which were savings of private corporations and cooperatives. The total amount of net retained earnings for 1969 was Baht 2,358.0 million, of which Baht 1,226.2 million were the savings of public corpora- tions and Baht 1,131.8 million the savings of private corpora- tions and cooperatives. Ideally, the allocation base for this kind of income would be the distribution of investment income by income classes. This statistical series, however, is not available in Thailand. The following arbitrary allocation rules, there- fore, were used: 1. Savings of government enterprises 1963 1969 Total amount (Baht million) 555 1 1226.2 (a) 25 percent allocated on a per family basis 138.8 306.5 (b) 75 percent allocated on a total expenditure basis 416.3 919.7 2. Savings of private corporations 1963 1969 Total amount (Baht million) 264.6 1131.8 (a) 80 percent allocated to the top income bracket 211.7 905.4 (b) 20 percent allocated by income distribution 52. \D 226.4 The simple- SE theoretical of these we conpanies a could be US benefit 11011 private COmj holds most < being held 1 the renainir cane distrit The ings by inco and 2.9. The .' e. . ._.e mclusior hated. The A c c? “021 the 196 “i'TOUHted to Cited. But inc 1 Die C1385 o‘ ' - ~ indlrect 3L4, . usalned fr, 81 The reasoning behind the above allocations is quite simple. Savings in the hands of public corporations should, theoretically, be shared by all households. Thus, 25 percent of these were allocated on a per family basis. But public companies also operate like private firms, and their savings could be used to expand or improve the services which would benefit households according to their spending patterns. For private companies, it is assumed that the top income bracket holds most of the shares of stock; only a small proportion being held by lower income groups. Hence the allocation of the remaining 20 percent of private corporate savings by in- come distributional pattern. The distribution of the net corporate retained earn- ings by income classes is shown in column 5 of Tables 2.8 and 2.9. Indirect Taxes The last adjustment in the income concept involves the inclusion of indirect taxes in the income thus far esti- mated. The amount of indirect taxes to be included are taken from the 1963 and 1969 national income accounts. These taxes amounted to Baht 6,461.1 million in 1963 and Baht 14,206.9 million in 1969. Thus far the matter is simple and uncompli- cated. But the method used in allocating these taxes among income classes is more difficult. The distributive pattern of indirect tax burdens by size of classes of income must be obtained from Chapter 3 of this study which deals with tax in: go ii: '13: It, 82 incidence. Then, based on this pattern, these taxes are al- located to different income classes. The distribution of in- direct taxes by income classes is presented in column 6 of Tables 2.8 and 2.9. The Adjusted Income Concept Now that all necessary adjustments have been accom- plished, the final step is to total all the income elements. The distribution of the adjusted income for the whole country by income classes in 1963 and 1969 is presented in Tables 2.8 and 2.9 The Lorenz curves for the two new distributions of income are shown in Figure 2.3. It is clear from Tables 2.8 and 2.9 and Figure 2.3 that the relative income positions of households in lower- income brackets has improved considerably compared to the dis— tribution of money income as shown in Table 2.7. For example, the income share of the lowest income bracket rose from 13.0 percent to 19.7 percent in 1963, and from 3.7 percent to 6.0 percent in 1969. Similarly the share of the top income group in the adjusted income distribution fell from 33.5 percent to 30.4 percent in 1963, and from 52.3 percent to 48.5 per- cent in 1969. In terms of the degree of income inequality, the Gini concentration ratios for the distributions of ad- justed income are estimated at .4559 and .4822 for 1963 and 1969, respectively, an overall improvement in income equality from the distribution of money income. This improvement is, of course, to be expected. Income in kind alone played a 83 .uxma mom “mousom o.ooa m.mve.mva m.mo~.va o.mmm.~ m.mm¢.m~ H.mmh.m o.mmm.hm o.mmo.em mommmHU Mac m.me m.mmm.o> m.m-.m m.ome.a m.aoa.m m.anm.a m.amm.a~ h.mbn.mm um>o use ooo.ma m.m m.omm.m m.>mo.a H.mm o.m~m m.omH H.mam.~ m.mnm.¢ mmm.>a I coo.mH H.h N.>hm.oa n.mom.a h.mma m.an N.Hmm H.vmh.~ N.mmm.m mmm.va I ooo.~a o.m H.mao.ma o.w>v.a h.oma m.moo.m m.mm~ m.mma.m o.mmm.m mmm.HH I ooo.m m.HH >.mom.ma n.>m>.H n.mma m.mao.v m.mHm m.mmm.m m.m>m.m mmm.m I ooo.o m.HH m.mem.ha m.emm.a m.mom m.mHH.m v.mhm m.>oa.m v.mmm.m mmm.m I ooo.m o.o m.bmn.m m.o~m «.mva w.mao.v m.~HH m.>hm.a o.amv.~ ooo.m Home: Amy Any Ame Amy Avv Amv Amy Adv coo W... .3 a... rage. I 85 and 838m I886 969: mmxme oofiflom a» E mucus 5 mucus mono: flame menxxa” uomuHoCH mumwmeoU meoocH lymphom Imenoe. mommoao meoocH Bumsflea meoocH Hmcomnmm Assam no 8832 5 3528 $3 .8826 9065 so .8588. 8.83 B .285 EEHE mo aofisfihflouéd flame “(when a» H U uric. V: F \‘Ih Fr!- I; ”IO: 84 .88» 0mm 588m o.ooa e.oma.ms H.eee.e s.mem n.mom.ee e.oos.~ m.mev.- ~.Hme.em mommmeo flea m.om ~.e~m.m~ e.omm.a m.~mm m.amm e.~em m.emo.m H.mem.HH um>o use ooo.ma m.HH e.mmm.m H.mms ~.me m.~me e.mem m.mve.~ s.aem.e mmm.~e I ooo.me o.e~ m.m~s.ma o.eee.e m.mee m.mom.a m.m~s H.0mm.m e.mmo.m mmm.HH I ooo.e m.ee m.em~.ee H.oeo.e e.eoe H.meo.~ N.emm m.mmm.~ a.~mm.e emm.m I ooo.m m.me m.eee.me m.mee.e m.nsa e.eam.e H.H~m e.s~e.~ H.ome.e ooo.m sous: Amy Ass rev Amy rev Amy Ame rev 9505 mmwm unease. oommmmm emphases m ”:H mmcaFHQm Jumps: . ease ca magma mucus. Aeneas 8“.an 853mm 5 Iugng 3 mafia awn—30 EH 985 §H§H 38088 285 . Iumzflea Eamon? 82 9505 gonna icon m0 963.3”: 5 muggy moma .mmmmmau 9505” an .mpcgmam 285” an .9505 “humane mo coflnflfimwid manna 85 8 I". G1963 ' '“559 f a l 8 I — — -_ 1963 ,I I 1969 I, be o 5 o a??? / G ‘0 1i Q) I! H do ,’ “3 6&0 I” R Q0 ’1 g 0‘9 1’ 3 3 . co / ,5 ’v" ,/ a ,/ U ’1 [I 8 i’ I/’ I O 20 “0 60 80 100 Cululative % of Families Figure 2.3--Distribution of Adjusted Income in Thailand: 1963 and 1969 W” H “in- VI tnLI' ist Loki. 86 very important part in raising the relative income positions of the lower income brackets. Various other income adjust- ments also helped smooth out greater disparities in the dis- tribution of cash income.38 One striking fact which must be emphasized, however, is that despite the improvement in income equality in the adjusted income distribution in both 1963 and 1969, the dis- tribution of adjusted income in 1969 is more unequal than the same distribution in 1963, as can be seen from the new set of Gini coefficients presented above. This is also evident from Figure 2.3, where the Lorenz curve of the 1969 adjusted in- come distribution lies clearly outside the 1963 Lorenz curve and farther away from the line of perfect equality. As the distributions of money income in 1963 and 1969 are practically the same, and with the new finding that the adjusted income distribution in 1969 is more unequal than the adjusted in- come distribution of 1963, one can confidently say that the income distribution of Thai households has deteriorated rather than improved. This is the case despite a marked increase in the rate of growth of the gross national product over the six years from 1963 to 1969.39 Two tentative reasons can be offered to explain this phenomenon. First, as income in kind is accrued to rural households relatively more than urban households and is the most important income element that substantially raises the income positions of the lower income brackets, the fact that 87 adjusted income distribution is worsened in 1969 compared to 1963 could mean that lower income households are deprived of opportunities to receive this nonmoney income. This is possible if a large number of rural poor families imigrate into cities or urban areas and face the usual unemployment problems and other living hardships. At the same time,they are foregoing their usual income in kind in the form of food grown for own consumption. There is no study to substantiate the exact extent of rural to urban migration in Thailand,but the existence of such migration has been a well-known fact in the past ten years. Second, the urban wage and salaried earners,particular1y the self-employed modern entrepreneurs,have become much better off economically also in the past ten years relative to the self-employed farmers. This could contribute to the situa— tion where the total income positions of the upper income brackets are rising too fast for the lower income brackets to catch up, thus widening the existing income gap instead of narrowing it. As has been discussed, two income concepts are avail- able to this study: money income and adjusted income. Which of these should be used? Despite its extended coverage, one must always realize that the adjusted income concept is more or less an artificial figure incorporating various elements (if arbirtrary adjustments. As such, it should not be taken as the sole legitimate income concept to be used in a budget incidence study. The best policy seems to be to use both 17WC311ey income, which is derived more or less objectively from (D "1 88 the surveys, and adjusted income, which is more artificial but more complete, as bases for this incidence study. The use of both income bases in this study has an- other advantage: It gives the range within which the income redistributional effects of the public sector can be examined. To elaborate, suppose that the burden of the total tax sys- tem on a representative household in income class A amounts to 50 percent of its money income compared to a burden of 25 percent for a family in income class B. On a money income basis alone, it would appear that households in income class A are taxed twice as heavily as households in income class B. However, when an adjusted income base is used to compute the relative tax incidence, it is found that households in income class A bear a total tax burden equal to 20 percent of their adjusted income, whereas households in income class B bear a total tax burden equal to 15 percent of their adjusted in- come. In this case, then, the relative tax burden that falls on households in income class A is only about 33 percent high- er than the relative tax burden of households in income class B. The "band" of differential tax incidence, therefore, ranges from 33 to 100 percent depending upon the income con- 40 cepts used. Thus, the use of adjusted income as another in- come base gives a more accurate picture of the incidence of fiscal activities than does using either of these income bases alone. d 89 Summary and Conclusions This chapter began with a general discussion of the conceptual and statistical difficulties facing a researcher attempting to estimate the distribution of income in an under- developed country. Despite many formidable obstacles, such an estimate is possible, and if carefully done it can be quite reliable. In Thailand the workable sources of data are two sample household surveys conducted in 1962-1963 and 1968- 1969. From these two surveys, and the information on the number of households from two population censuses, the money income distribution for each year has been estimated. The result shows that, using the Gini concentration ratio as the chosen index of income inequality, the money income distribu- tion in 1969 is slightly less unequal than that in 1963, but, overall, both income distributions were very unequal by any standard. To build a more complete income base, various income adjustments have been carried out. First, the already es- timated money income was used as the basic element of personal income in the national income accounting sense. It was then adjusted for the underreporting of income and for imputed rents. Other major adjusting elements included income in kind, net corporate retained earnings, and indirect taxes. The final comprehensive income concept, termed "adjusted in- come," was shown to be similar in principle to the "adjusted family income" concept used by Joseph Pechman and Benjamin 90 Okner in their study of United States tax incidence for 1966. The new adjusted income distribution shows considerable im- provement in equality over the money income distribution be- cause the income of the lower income brackets has been augment— ed, mostly through income in kind. The distribution or ad- justed income in 1969, however, has become more unequal since 1963. Both money income and adjusted income will be used as bases for computing the effective rates of tax burden and ex- penditure benefits discussed in the next two chapters. In conclusion, it should be stated that although the income estimates obtained in this study are the result of a very careful investigation, they cannot claim to be the de- finitive estimates of income distribution in Thailand. The basic survey data used for computing the income distribution have many defects. For example, income classifications were inconsistent between rural and urban households, income is considerably underreported, and nonmoney income does not re- ceive adequate attention. While the income of the lower and middle income classes is presumably adequately tabulated, the income of the upper income groups probably is not. If any- thing, the present income distribution estimate probably does not overstate the income position of the lower income groups; rather, the income positions of the upper income groups, es- pecially the highest one in this study (Baht 18,000 and over), is more than likely biased downward. A final remark as to the nature of income distribution thus far estimated in this study should be made. This income 91 distribution is known as a "pre-fisc" or original income dis- tribution; it shows the relative income positions of house- holds by income classes before the effects of taxes of all kinds are deducted and the real benefits of government expendi- tures converted into money terms are added. It is the distri- bution which would have prevailed if the Thai government were to substitute the present tax and expenditure programs with an income-proportional tax and expenditure program. In anticipation of what is to follow in Chapters 4 and 5, it should be noted here that the term "post-tax" in- come distribution is reserved for the pre-fisc distribution, where the absolute tax burdens have been deducted. By the same token, a "post-benefit" income distribution is the re— sulting income distribution when the monetized benefits of government expenditures have been added to the pre—fisc in- come distribution. Finally, the "post-fisc" income distribu- tion is obtained when the net benefits of government fiscal activities--that is, expenditure benefits minus tax burdens—- are added to the pre-fisc income distribution. The extent of income redistribution of the entire fiscal system, there- fore, is seen through comparison of the pre-fisc and the post-fisc income distributions. FOOTNOTES 1This chapter deals strictly with the problems and procedures of the estimation of income distribution; it is not concerned with the theories of income distribution or the explanation as to why the income is so distributed in a par- ticular way. Neither is it concerned with the sources of income disparities within various sectors of the economy. These are certainly important, but they are beyond the scope of this study. For a concise summary of the theories of income distribution see, for example, Martin Bronfenbrenner, Income Distribution Theory_(Chicago: Aldine Atherton, Inc., 1971), Chapter 3; Jan Pen, Income Distribution (New York: Praeger, 1971), Chapter 6. - 2Henry C. Simons, Personal Income Taxation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1938), p. 50. 3Robert M. Haig, "The Concept of Income" in The Federal Income Tax, ed. R. M. Haig (New York: Columbia University Press, 1921), p. 26. 4That the sources of data are divided into four cate- gories does not imply that each source is entirely independ— ent of one another. Indeed a combination of techniques using some or all of the above data sources is common and has been used by many investigators especially in the situation where no single data source is sufficient or is decidedly better than the others. Research ingenuity is required here to see which information is needed and how to get it. Two good ex- amples of the use of these techniques are the studies by Milton C. Taylor and associates and by Charles E. McLure, Jr. on the Colombian income distribution in 1962 and 1970 re- spectively. In these studies the sources of data included, among other things, the tax rolls, the national income accounts, the urban population surveys, surveys of urban industrial workers, the agricultural household surveys, the estimates of the labor force, and the population census. See Milton C. Taylor e31§1., Fiscal Survey of Colombia, a Report Prepared under the Direction of the Joint.Tax Program, (Baltimore: published for the Joint Tax Program of the Organization of American States and the Inter-American Development Bank by the John Hopkins University, 1965), and Charles E. McLure, Jr., "The Incidence of Colombian Taxes, 1970," Discussion Paper No. 41, Rice University, summer, 1973 (Mimeographed). 92 93 5 . . . Harry T. Oshima, "Income Inequality and Economic Growth: The Postwar Experience of Asian Countries," Malayan Economic Review, 15 (October, 1970), pp. 7-41. 6United Nations, Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East, The 1971 Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East (Bangkok, 1972), Chapter 3; Idem., Interregional Trade Pro- jection, Effective Protection and Income Distribution. Vol- ume III: Income Distribution (Bangkok, 1972), part 6. 7Udom Kerdphibule, "Income and the Distribution of Income of Agricultural Sector," Thai Journal of Agricultural Economics, 11 (December, 1972), pp. 1-24. 8For example, the data that Kerdphibule claimed to be 1970 data were actually the 1968-1969 data. The treatment of the mean incomes of the two open-ended brackets in 1963 were rather crude. One was also surprised at the acceptance with- out any reservation of the distribution of income of rice farmers in the Central Plain even when the data were gathered from the survey of a single village of less than 300 families. 9William A. McCleary, "Sources of Change in Distribu- tion of Income in Thailand, 1962/63 and 1968/69," Discussion Paper No. 26, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, August, 1972 (Mimeographed). loDr. Oey Astra Meesook, who is probably the best known authority on income distribution in Thailand today, has con- sented to supply some of her unpublished income distribution data for use in this study. 11The information from the reports of this Survey would be used for the fiscal year 1963. Also for comparison pur- poses, the town-village classification would be taken to mean the same as urban-rural classification. 12In the 1968-1969 household expenditure survey, only the average annual money income figures were given, and they were consistent with the income class limit (no class jumping). In most cases, the average income of each class was very close to the midpoint of that class. 13There is no sacrifice in the analysis, however, be- cause the aim of this study is to deal with fiscal incidence at the national level only. Only the national distribution of income would be needed. 14Specifically, the proportion of the average income of the bottom class to that of the next higher class in 1969 is about .40, and the proportion of the average income of the second top bracket to that of the top bracket is about .45. However, the latter figure represented the urban income only. 94 For the country as a whole, this proportion would be less be- cause it was likely that the average income in the rural top bracket would be slightly less than that in the urban top bracket. A ratio of .46, then, would be more appropriate. When these ratios were used to multiply the midpoints of the second bottom and the second top brackets in 1963, the re- sults were 1800 and ll7,500--the mean incomes of the bottom and the top income classes in 1963 respectively. Bracket by bracket, the 1963 average income was larger than that in 1969 which should not be. But no adjustment was made for fear that the distribution pattern in 1963, which was of interest here, might be affected. 15Discussions on the Pareto distribution could be found in Jan Pen; Lawrence R. Klein, An Introduction to Econo- metrics (Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1962); H. Lydall, The Structure of Earnings (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1968). 16To estimate the minimum income, Y in the Pareto distribution, the quantile method was used.0 This method re- quires that, first, two probability levels, P1 and P2 be chosen which correspond to two levels of income, y and Y2. P1 and P2 are simply the percentages of the total households having income less than y, and y2 respectively. Then from a form of the Pareto function: b b p. = 1- [12] and p. = I-[¥_oo H.ees m.mee o.mm m.mo~ m.ema o.sme mmaaodocoz u.>oo o.-m m.ms ~.mm o.es o.mm o.om mmofl>umm one modem u.>oo o.-v e.HmHI s.oe m.os e.ee H.~e mangoes new mmsuamsom v.5ee e.mm m.ea o.em m.me o.m~ suuoaoum :0 waxes ~.mem m.em e.em ~.moe e.ee «.me mmxme uuodxm umnuo e.mms «.mee ~.mm ~.mm~ H.mee e.eee masseuse muse m.eee.~ H.ome m.emm e.mee «.mme «.mme moaned usedeH m.ooe e.ms m.em e.moa m.me m.mm mmxme mmemm m>suooeom m.aem.e m.eem ~.eme H.emm e.mm~ e.esm mmxme mmmcamsm ~.~Hm o.~oe m.mm e.me a.mv m.ae xme oeoocH openeduoo ~.mee H.eme H.4H II II II xme msoocH eases>flecH mommmeo um>o can mmm.na mam.ee amm.m ooo.m sea ooo.me Iooo.~H Iooc.e Iooo.m “was: Aunmmv mommmau mEoocH mmxme we mdha Aucmm mo mcowaaflz cwmucsoeo cam mmm§H mmmJH mmmJa mmm.m mmmfi ooo.m . H2 Iooo.wH Iooo.m._.. Iooo.NH Iooo.m Ioood loco.m “OED mmxme MO was? 32mm: mommmau mEoocH Seam mo 9832.: 5 8588 $3 8888 285 so 885m 58. 338nm mo Sflsflfimaolma Some. 129 income levels that tends to exaggerate the significance of data in some parts of the income distribution and to diminish it in others, the third method is more attractive. It is a most useful complement to the other two methods because it can be used to compare the tax burdens of groups representing the same number or percentage of family units in different parts of the income scale. It must be pointed out, however, that Pechman and Okner had at their disposal complete observations of total households and total income (from the so-called MERGE file) which enabled them easily to compute the effective tax rates by decile or percentile groups. Unfortunately, similar data are not available in Thailand. Although it is possible to estimate a Lorenz curve of tax burdens in this study from which effective rates by decile or percentile groups could be computed using numerical analysis and computer techniques, this would be unusually complicated, and it was decided that it would not be desirable. As a result, only two methods of tax incidence presentation will be adopted here. The two are: Effective Tax Rates by Income Classes Effective rates for 13 different types of taxes by income classes are presented in Tables 3.4 and 3.5. These effective rates were based on the money income of households in 1963 and 1969. Tables 3.6 and 3.7 present the effective tax rates based on adjusted income of households in 1963 and 1969 respectively. 130 m.m~ m.om o.mm m.~m v.m~ h.~v Hmuoe h.o v.0 o.o n.o m.o m.H “mayo n.o v.0 o.o m.o m.o a.a mmmflumumuam u.>oo m.~ m.H m.m m.~ m.~ ~.a mmaaomocoz u.>oo m.o 0.0 m.o m.o H.H m.a mmow>uwm pom mmamm u.>oo N.H n.a m.o m.o o.a m.a muafiumm pom mmfiuammom v.0 m.o ¢.o m.o v.0 m.o muummoum co mmxme H.H m.o H.H N.H m.H H.H mwxme uuomxm umzuo m.m o.H o.~ m.m m.m m.m mEoHEwum mowm o.m o.m m.s m.s H.m m.va .mmfluso anomaH ~.H 5.0 N.H N.H w.a H.m mmxme mmamm m>fluomamm m.v o.m v.¢ m.v m.m v.m mmxma mmmCflmsm m.o m.o m.o m.o m.o v.a xme meoooH mumuomuou v.H m.m m.o II II II xmB mEoocH Hmspfl>HoQH mmmmmau uw>o com mmm.ha mmm.HH amm.m ooo.m Had ooo.ma nooo.ma uooo.m looo.m noon: mmxme mo mama Aunmmv mommmao wEoocH mmma .mmmmmHo mEoocH xn mEoocH wmcoz co pwmmm mmuom Ammmmucmoummv xma m>wuommmmunv.m magma 131 5.00 5.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.50 00000 0.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.5 00000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000000000 0.000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 000000000200.>00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0000>000 000 00000 0.000 0.0 0.0 - 5.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 0.0 0005000 000 000000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000000 00 00000 5.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00x00 000000 00000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 05005000 0000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.00 000000 000050 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00x00 00000 0>0000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00x05 00000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 x09 050000 000000000 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 In I. .: x00 050000 00000>0000 0000000 00>0 000 000.50 000.00 000.00 000.0 000.0 000.0 000. I000.00 -000.00 -000.00 -000.0 -000.0 -000.0 00000 00005 00 0059 3:000 0000000 050000 0000000000000 0000 .0000000 050000 00 050000 00002.00 00000 00000:x00 0>0uummmmrnm.m 00000 132 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 00000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000 m.o 0.o m.o m.o m.o 0.0 mmmwumumucm u.>ou 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0000000002 0.>oo 0.o m.o 0.o v.o m.o m.o mm00>0mm com mmamm u.>ow 0.0 0.¢ 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0000000 000 000000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000000 00 00000 m.o 0.o 0.0 0.o 0.o m.o mmxma uuomxm umsuo 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 .05000000 0000 0.0 5.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 000000 000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000 00000 0>0000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000 00000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 000 000000 0000000oo 0.0 0.0 N.o II II II x09 mEoocH 009©0>wch 0000000 00>o 0:0 000.50 000.00 000.0 000.0 000 u000.00 [000.00 I000.0 -000.0 00000 00000 00 0000 Aunmmv mommMHU mEoocH mmma .mmmmMHU mEoooH an mEoocH omumsmom co ommmm mmumm Ammmmuomoummv x09 m>wuommmmulo.m manna 133 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 00000. 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0050 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000000000 0.80 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000082 0.80 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000000 000 00000 0.80 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0000000 000 000000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.00 00000000 00 00000. 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000. 000000 00000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0. 0.0 0.0 0.500000 0000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0. 0.0 0.0 0.0 00008 000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0020.0. 00000 90000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00000. 00000000 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 00.0 00800 00000008 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 -u I I I 00.0. 00800 0000000000 .03 0,... -00 -00 -00 -00 -00 0... 000 0000.0. 00 000.0. 000000 0000000 00800 0000000000000 0000 .0000000 00800 00 00800 00000000 00 00000 00000 00.0 0>0000000I00 0000.0. 134 Let us first consider the effective rates based on money income. On the average, the 1969 tax collections appeared to have imposed heavier burdens on families as a whole than was the case in 1963 (28.7 percent compared with 25.5 percent). On a class by class basis, the tax incidence of both years shows a generally regressive trend from the lowest to the highest income bracket. In 1963, the lowest income group contributed 42.7 percent of its money income to the government in tax payments, whereas the highest group contributed only 20.8 percent of its money income. The corresponding figures in 1969 were 47.0 percent and 25.7 percent for the lowest and highest income classes, respectively. The trend of effective tax rate is distinctly regressive for the first few income groups, but this tapers off in the higher income brackets. In any case, the t0p income group bore the least tax burden relative to its income position in both years. When effective tax rates were computed using adjusted income as the denominator, the incidence picture changed markedly. The generally regressive trend which characterized the effective tax rates based on money income is now absent. Instead, the new effective tax rates for both years show a mildly fluctuating trend which can at best be described as proportional. In 1963 the average effective tax rate for all income classes was 11.3 percent; in 1969, the same rate was 12.7 percent. In both years, the lowest income bracket 135 still bore a higher tax burden than the national average and the highest income bracket lower. In 1963 households in the lowest income bracket seem to have suffered the most from taxation relative to households in other income posi- tions, which was also true for 1969. But since the effective tax rates varied only about 2 percentage points among income classes, it is perhaps apprOpriate to call the tax system proportional in both years. The pattern of the effective rates also can be depicted graphically, as shown in Figures 3.1 and 3.2. Here, a line which connects all the points corresponding to the effective rates of each income level roughly indicates the progressive or regressive nature of the tax system. A line that generally slopes downward would indicate a regressive incidence pattern, and one which generally slopes upward a progressive pattern. For a proportional incidence pattern, the line would be somewhat parallel to the horizontal axis. As can be seen in Figures 3.1 and 3.2, the tax incidence patterns in 1963 and 1969 were almost identical; they were shown to be mildly to moderately regressive across the income range under a money income base, and somewhat proportional under an adjusted income base. It is possible, in fact instructive, to show the trend of the tax programs in 1963 and 1969 by regressing the ef- fective tax rates upon the average money income of a repre- sentative household in each income class. The $10pe of the 136 mom“ was new" .mouuuao onoocm an .onoouH 50:0: co cocoa nevus was o>avoouhmutdwm magmas $28 no messages uouuaao oaoocH ma mu NH 0 o n o lllllllllllllllllllllll : ON 1!! ii!!!) A 0: $2 mead lllllllllll : om Avsoouomv moans use ObnvOOMhm 137 mood can mom“ .nonmuao o-oocH up .nnoosH voooshv< so conga nouum was o>aaoommanu~.n «Mamas Apron mo acnuusonev noon-Ho osooca ma ms Nu m o m o HHH lllll Jul llllllllllllllll I lllllllllllllllllll ,hHHIIIllflulllllll tIIIIIIIIx . ow to: moma11, mom“ nnnnnnnnn s om Aesoouomv moans nae ObHfiOOMMH 138 tax incidence regression curve is useful in indicating the regressivity or progressivity of the tax system: a negative SIOpe would mean a regressive tax system, a positive slope a progressive tax system, and a zero slope a proportional tax system. After fitting the curve, it is shown in Table 3.8 that, based on money income, the 1963 and 1969 tax programs were quite regressive, with the earlier slightly more regressive than the latter programs. But with adjusted income as a base, although the tax programs were still slightly regressive, the regressivity was reduced to almost zero, signifying a tendency toward proportionality in the tax systems. As for the tax burdens by type of taxes in 1963 and 1969, most taxes were regressive throughout, with the notable exception, of course, of the personal income tax, for which the top income class and one or two classes below it bore all of the burdens and the lower income classes none. But although only a few higher income brackets bore the burden of the income tax, this burden relative to the income of the highest bracket is quite small: only 3.9 and 3.2 percent for the tOp income group in 1963 and 1969, respectively. As expected, all major indirect taxes, such as busi- ness taxes, selective sales taxes, and import duties showed a pronounced regressive pattern, especially in the lower income brackets. Another tax which was particularly burden- some to the lower income groups was the rice premium, 139 Table 3.8--Generalized Tax Incidence Functions “Effective Tax Rates) = a + b (Annual Average Money Income) ] Intercept SlOpe R (1) On Money Income Base 1963 33.3 -.390 .9562 1969 37.1 -.375 .9638 (2) On Adjusted Income Base 1963 12.4 -.056 .9992 1969 13.4 -.003 .9922 aAverage Annual Money Income is in Thousands of Baht 140 especially in 1969. Other taxes, which did not show a clearly regressive trend, showed a U-shaped pattern where the lowest and the highest income brackets bore a higher burden than the middle income brackets. These taxes include the corporate income tax, taxes on property, royal— ties and fees. All other government revenues had a mildly regressive incidence pattern throughout. This is quite understandable and, indeed, to be expected, since the bulk of the nontax revenues came from such sources as tobacco and distillery monOpolies and lottery operations, products which are not consumed in proportion to income. The Effects of Tax Programs on the Distribution of Income As the tax structures in 1963 and 1969 appear to be regressive across the whole range of money income, one can reason that income distribution after taxation would become more unequal. This is demonstrated in Table 3.9 which presents the results of the after-tax money income distribu- tion after the absolute amount of taxes is deducted from pre—tax money incane distribution. In Table 3.9, one immediately sees that, under a money income base, the distribution of income became more unequal over the period for the lower income groups. In 1963, the lowest two income groups suffered relatively more than other groups from tax incidence, while in 1969, all but the top two income brackets experienced a deterioration 141. o .2: o .2: o . 03 o .03 o .2: o .ooa 063 o 63 mommmao a? m.m¢ m.mv m.om m.om v.¢m m.~m n.mm m.mm um>o can ooo.ma >.m m.m m.m m.m mam.~alooo.ma m.AH A m.HH A m.mH A A.ma m.m A.n m.> H.m mmm.qa|ooo.ma m.m o.m H.m m.m mmm.aancoo.m o.vm A o.qm A m.nm A v.m~ m.HH w.AH m.oa m.oa mom.m Iooo.m H.~A m.HH m.va m.va n.m m.m m.ma o.¢H mmm.m loco.m o.w o.o m.ma m.ma m.~ n.m o.oa o.ma ooo.m “was: xMBiumom omHmeum xme1umom omfimlmum xmg1umom omflmlmum xmBWHmom omHmeum Esme $3 $3 $3 $3 mommflu 9505 833“me 8.85 Bums“? :Qfifixmuumwanmikxnnmucnz Ammmflcwoume $3 o5 82 .3988 885 E 8.85 8pm: Pa Em ammo: xmebmom can 03QO .«6 :oflsflflma mmflfioummlm .m manna 142 in their relative income positions. Under the adjusted income base, the changes in post—tax income distribution was small in both years but the tOp income groups is still shown to have improved its income position. The changes in the distribution of income after-tax are presented in Table 3.10 in terms of Gini concentration ratios. Although Table 3.10 reveals nothing new, it does give concise, quantitative support to the previous conclu- sions that: (1) being generally regressive, Thailand's tax programs in 1963 and 1969 caused the post-tax income distribution to become more unequal in both years, but (2) the extent of increase in inequality however, was slightly less severe under the 1969 than the 1963 tax programs. Table 3.10 may be examined in the following manner: First, using the money income base, the 1963 tax system caused a deterioration of income equality, as measured by the Gini concentration ratio, by 8.4 percent (that is, comparing post- tax to pre-fisc income distribution), whereas in 1969 the percentage of equality deterioration was 5.4 percent. If the pre-fisc and post-tax income distributions in 1963 are compared to the respective distributions in 1969, income inequality in the latter year is shown to have been reduced by 1.4 percent and 4.2 percent, respectively. This point requires further clarification. If the existing tax programs in 1963 and 1969 were replaced by income proportional taxes. the improvement of money income distribution in 1969 over 143 oo.ou mAmq. mmmv. mead mo.q+A An.m+ A Ho.A+ moms. mmmv. moma wmmm msoocH omumsno< :o Ame A z A mm.m+ 54mm. ommm. amma mA.eu hm.A- av.m+ Noam. nmmm. mood ommm mEoocH.mm:oz so AHV mflwme «wwme mauanmmmz wwwme «HMWMH xmelumom omflmlmum ucmflowmmuou xmelumom omwmlwum mmma cam mama cmmzumm ficfio :H A+V Ham» mummuocH Mo ucmflofluumoo Acflo Ans mmmmuoma mucmfioflmmmoo ficflu CH A+v mmmmuocH no mmmucmoum AIV ommmuomo mumucmoumm m mood pom moma .huflamsvmcH mEoocH cw momcmso mmmucmoumm paw mowumm coaumuucmocoo wcwo xmelumom can omHmIoumuloa.m manna 144 that in 1963 would have been about 1.4 percent. With the direct effects of the existing tax systems upon the income of households, however, the post-tax 1969 income distribution is improved over the same distribution in 1963 by 4.2 percent. Therefore, it could be concluded that, based on money income, the 1969 tax programs had.a smaller income de-equalizing effect than the 1963 tax programs, and such an effect worsened the index of income equality by about 2.8 percentage points (that is, 4.2 minus 1.4) less than would have been the case without the present tax programs. On the adjusted income base, however, the changes within the year were quite small. In 1963, the tax programs worsened the Gini coefficient by just over one percent. On the contrary, in 1969 the tax programs seemed to have im- proved the post-tax income distribution but only by less than one-tenth of one percent. This change is much too small to be given any significance; it is likely to have been caused by a statistical error. A more credible conclusion would be that the 1969 tax programs had neutral or zero effect upon the post-tax adjusted income distribution of households in Thailand. Also, as is shown in Table 3.10, the preefisc income distribution was about 5.8 percent more unequal in 1969 compared to 1963. The fact that the post-tax income distribution in 1969 was still 4.7 percent more unequal than the post-tax income distribution in 1963 means that the 1969 tax programs had reduced income inequality by 145 about 1.1 percentage points over the 1963 programs. Obviously, the equalizing effect of the 1969 programs was still much too weak to overwhelm the de-equalizing influences outside the tax sector. In summary, the tax programs in Thailand contributed in varying degrees to the worsening of income equality within 1963 and 1969. Although over time the tax systems were less conducive to income de-equalization, they were still far from being an instrument for income redistribution from the rich to the poor. Summary and Conclusion This chapter has attempted to estimate the incidence of Thailand's total tax system in 1963 and 1969. First, the theoretical problems confronting a tax incidence study were discussed, and the justification for the methods used in the present study was given. The general methodology to be followed requires that the taxes and other revenues be selected, and then, based on certain shifting assumptions and allocation formulas, these taxes in absolute amounts be allocated to households by size classes of income. Next, these absolute burdens are divided by the income base of each income class, resulting in effective tax rates. These rates show the percentages of income which households are assumed to have contributed to the government in taxes. The income redistributional effects of the government tax 146 programs can be seen either in the pattern of these effective rates across income classes or in the change in the post- tax distribution of income. Several general conclusions may be noted: (1) Based on money income, Thailand's programs were generally regressive across income classes, with the highest income bracket bearing a lower burden than all other brackets. (2) When the income base was changed from money to adjusted income, the tax incidence pattern changed from regressive to almost prOportional. This was mainly because adjusted income accounted for much of the increase in the income of the lower brackets. As a result, the effective tax rates of these lower income groups were significantly reduced. (3) Under the adjusted income base, it was clear that the government had not caused the distribution of income of households to become more unequal, but it also had not made it become significantly more equal. Nevertheless, one is inclined to suspect that the Thai tax system more likely contributed to the worsening of household income distribution rather than to its improvement, since the income of the upper income brackets was likely to be understated and that of the lower income brackets overstated on an adjusted income basis. (4) The above results also can be demonstrated by changes in the pattern of income distribution after absolute ta (ii an le ad ta UR 147 tax burdens are subtracted from the initial income distribution. Regarding money income, the post-tax distribution of income became more unequal for both 1963 and 1969, although the 1969 tax programs made it slightly less unequal than did the 1963 tax programs. Concerning adjusted income, the post-tax distribution of income remained practically unchanged although forces other than government tax policies caused initial income distribution to become more unequal. (5) Finally, what is particularly disquieting about the general tax incidence picture is that the effective burdens of the highest income group still are lower than the effective burdens of the lowest income group. For this reason alone, the tax system deserves to be reevaluated. 148 FOOTNOTES 1See Richard A. Musgrave, The Theory of Public Finance (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1959), Chapter 1. 2Richard A. Musgrave et a1" "Distribution of Tax Payments by Income Class: A Case Study for 1948" National Tax Journal, 4 (March, 1951): 1-48. 3It is counterfactual because it is against the fact: the government or the tax system cannot simply be assumed away. The term was first used by Eugene Smolensky and his associates. See Jean Behrens and Eugene Smolensky, "Alterna- tive Definitions of Income Redistribution," Public Finance, 28 (1973), pp. 315-332, and Morgan Reynolds and Eugene Smolensky, "The Post-Fisc Distribution: 1961 and 1970 Com- pared," National Tax Journal, 27 (December, 1974), pp. 515— 530. 4Alan R. Prest, "Statistical Calculations of Tax Burdens," Economica, 22 (August, 1955): PP. 234-45. Prest also quoted Edwin Canaan as saying that "such an inquiry (tax incidence study) is a'will-o-the-wisp' and absolutely useless." 5Carl S. Shoup, Public Finance (Chicago: Aldine, 1969); Richard M. Bird and Luc De Wulf, "Taxation and Income Distribution in Latin America: A Critical Review of Empirical Studies," IMF Staff Papers, 23 (November, 1973), pp. 639-81. 6Richard A. Musgrave, "Estimating the Distribution of the Tax Burden," Chapter 2 in Problems of Tax Administration in Latin America: Papers and Proceedings of a Conference held in Buenos Aires, Argentina, October, 1961 (Baltimore, 1965): pp. 41-42. In fact, this differential incidence approach had already been used in the original Musgrave gt 31. study in 1951. 7Arnold C. Harberger,"The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax," Journal of Political Economy, 70, (June, 1962): pp. 215-240. 8Shoup, Chapter 2. 149 9Charles E. McLure, in spite of his high praise of Harberger model as "a breakthrough in the analysis of tax incidence in his paper," General Equilibrium Incidence Analysis: The Harberger Model after Ten Years," Discussion Paper No. 37, Rice University, Fall, 1972, used conventional partial analysis in his tax incidence studies in West Malaysia, Colombia and Panama. 10Alan R. Prest, "The Budget and Interpersonal Distribution," Public Finance, 23 (1968), P. 92. 11Shoup, p. 11. 12From the surveys of tourist expenditures carried out by the Tourist Organization of Thailand (TOT) (Tourist Expenditure Surveys, Bangkok: TOT, various issuesL it was shown that the total expenditures by tourists in 1963 and 1969 were estimated at Baht 476.5 million and Baht 1406.3 million respectively. These were by no means small amounts, but it was impossible to know how much of these expenditures went to the government as taxes. The use of some nominal tax rates to compute the amount of taxes that were supposed to be paid by these tourists was hazardous; and considering the existing laxity in tax compliance and tax enforcement, the resultant tax figures were likely to overstate the actual taxes paid. In all, it was not unreasonable to assume that these taxes were small or would not greatly affect the total incidence pattern. 13For details of these allocation formulas, see Appendix D. 14 Musgrave, The Theory of Public Finance, pp. 232-40. 15Musgrave also argued that either the factor supplies could be assume fixed or that the effects of changes in relative factor prices on relative product prices could be ignored since factor proportions were likely to be very much the same for each combination of goods consumed at each different point on the income scale. In other words, the nominal burdens could be assumed to stay put. See his "Estimating the Distribution of the Tax Burden," in Income Redistribution and the Statistical Foundations of Economic Policy, eds. C. Clark and G. Struvel, (London: Bowes and Bowes, 1964). P. 201. 16See Marian Krzyzaniak and Richard A. Musgrave, The Shifting of the Corporate Income Tax (Baltimore: John Hopkins, 1963). 150 17For literature on this tOpic, see for example, Marian Krzyzaniak, ed., Effects of Corporate Income Tax (Detroit: Wayne State University, 1966); Richard S. Gordon, "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax in U. S. Manufacturing 1925-62," American Economic Review, 57 (September, 1967), pp. 731-58; John G. Cragg, Arnold C. Harberger and Peter Mieszkowski, "Empirical Evidence on the Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax," Journal of Political Economy, 75 (December, 1967), pp. 811-821; Peter Mieszkowski, "Tax Incidence Theory: The Effects of Taxes on the Distribu- tion of Income," The Journal of Economic Literature, 7 (December, 1969), pp. 1103-1124; T. Mathew, "Sh1fting and Incidence of Corporation Income Tax: A Review," The Indian Economic Journal, 20 (October-December, 197277' pp. 2574274. 18Bird and DeWulf, pp. 660-661. 19Jay S. Salkin, "On the Direct Measurement of Tax and Progression in Thailand," National Tax Journal, 27 (June, 1974), pp. 301-18. 20 The results of the distribution of tax burdens according to alternative shifting assumptions for corporate income tax practiced in most incidence studies will not be presented in this study because they were not substantially different from the results using full shifting assumption. This is not surprising, for the corporate tax collection was very small in Thailand contributing less than 5 percent of the total government revenues in either 1963 or 1969. 21Prest, "Statistical calculations . . ." 22Musgrave, "Estimating . . .," (1965), pp. 42-46. See also W. Irwin Gillespie, The Incidence of Taxes and Public Expenditures in the Canadian Economy (Ottawa: Queen's Printer, 1966), pp. 40-51. 23Allan M. Cartter, The Redistribution of Income in Postwar Britain: A Study of the Effects of the Central Government Fiscal Program in 1948-49 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1955), pp. 19-22. 24Earl R. Rolph, "A Proposed Revision of Excise- Tax Theory," Journal of Political Economy, 60 (April, 1952), pp. 102-117. 25See mainly Sriprinya Ramakomud, Thailand's Foreign Trade: Structure and Policy, 1951-60 (Bangkok: Kuruspha Press, 1968). 151 26 I I O O The researches on the 1nc1dence of r1ce prem1ums in Thailand were quite numerous; see for example Sura Sanittanont, Thailand’s Rice Export Tax: Its Effects on the Rice Economy (Bangkok: National Institute of Develop- ment Administration, 1967); Edward Van Roy, "The Pursuit of Growth and Stability Through Taxation of Agricultural Ex- ports: Thailand's Experience" Public Finance, 23 (1968), pp. 294-317; Trent Bertrand, "Rural Taxation in Tahiland," Pacific Affairs, 42 (Summer, 1969), pp. 178-188; James C. Ingram, Economic Change in Thailand, 1850—1970, 2nd ed. (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1971). 27See Wit Satyarakwit, "Tin: A Comparison of Gravel Pump and Dredging Mining," M. A. Thesis, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, August, 1971. 28Joseph Pechman and Benjamin Okner, Who Bears the Tax Burden? (Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1974). CHAPTER IV THE INCIDENCE OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURES While the previous chapter examined the revenue side of government activities and the subsequent distribution of tax burdens by size classes of income, this chapter will ex- amine the other side of the fiscal coin: public expenditures and the distribution of their benefits by income classes of households. As mentioned in Chapter 3, one of the main pur- poses of collecting taxes is to enable the government to pro- vide both general and specific goods and services to taxpayers. This process has repercussions on the income distribution of households, since each householder's tax paid is usually not matched by an equal amount of government expenditure for that household. Therefore, to account for the complete income re- distributional effects of a fiscal system, it is imperative that the incidence of public expenditures be evaluated, in ad- dition to the incidence of taxes. To omit this item would be tantamount to assuming either that the benefit incidence is neutral or that it is unimportant, neither of which view is tenable on an a priori basis. In estimating the income redistributional impact of public expenditure programs, a researcher faces problems much more severe than those encountered in estimating tax incidence. Most difficult of all are the theoretical and operational 152 153 issues of how to quantify the expenditure "benefits" and al- locate these to different income classes. The problems seem almost insurmountable when dealing with such "public goods" as national defense, public health and sanitation, public administration, and protection. Once these matters are dis- posed of, the rest of the procedure follows smoothly. The methodology in this study will be to establish some rules for allocating the quantified amounts of benefits to various in- come classes. Many of these rules are the same as those used earlier in the allocation of taxes. After all benefits are allocated to each income bracket, the effective rates of ex- penditure benefits or benefit incidence are then calculated by dividing such benefits by the income bases of each income bracket. Theoretical Problems in Expenditure Incidence Studies Broadly speaking, the theoretical questions involved in a benefit incidence study can be summed up as follows: (1) Who should be regarded as the beneficiaries of govern- ment spending: those who directly receive government money, or those who are ultimately affected by what the government does? (2) It is likely that there will be more than one group of households or one segment of the population which will re- ceive the benefits of (or be affected by) government spending. In this case, should one be interested mainly in the primary beneficiaries, or in the secondary and subsequent beneficiaries 154 as well? (3) How does one quantify the benefits expected to be received by the designated groups of households in the case of certain specific expenditures, or by the population as a whole in the case of general public expenditures? (4) Is it necessary to determine the true beneficiaries? Can one discuss the benefits of government expenditures without knowing who the actual beneficiaries are? These questions will be discussed in detail below. Money Flow Versus Benefit Approach Two approaches may be used in analyzing the incidence of expenditure benefits: the money flow approach and the benefit approach.1 The first would concentrate only on the actual recipients of direct payments made by the government either in exchange for goods and services or as transfers, without considering who would ultimately benefit from those services. For example, salary payments to public teachers would be considered benefits to the teachers themselves. ‘While students obviously also would benefit from this educational expenditure, such benefits are not considered in the money flow approach. The second, or benefit, approach emphasizes the end results of public spending; of concern is the eventual beneficiary, not the recipient of any money payments. In the case of the educational expenditure mentioned above, for ex- ample, the final beneficiaries under the benefit approach would be the students and their families, not the teachers. In the case of defense spending, it is the entire population 155 which enjoys the benefit of protection, not the military per- sonnel employed or the firms under contract to produce arma- ments. While the money flow approach is more appropriate when dealing with governmental transfers whose recipients are believed to be the final beneficiaries, it is inadequate in nontransfer cases and in the situation where the government provides substandard or no services. Moreover, as Adler has pointed out, the money flow concept is based on an implicit assumption that the income of government employees would be zero if the government did not employ them, which of course is not always true in the real world; if the government did not employ them, they often would find work elsewhere.2 As the foregoing indicates, it is conceptually more plausible and useful to evaluate the effects of government services in terms of the final beneficiary, not the recipient of govern- ment funds spent on a certain public project. Generally, therefore, the benefit approach is adopted in most fiscal in— cidence studies. Direct and Indirect Recipients of Benefits When the government spends its money, it must have in mind who will be the first to receive the benefits directly. If the spending is on educational services, the children at- tending school and their families would be the primary re- cipients; if the spending is on road building, the road users would be the direct recipients, and so on. This does not mean, 156 however, that the effects of the benefits would terminate with the primary beneficiaries. More than likely, there will be countless circumstances in which secondary or other in- direct beneficiaries exist. For example, an increase in the number of students or educational activities would also boost book production and the income of teachers, and an increase in road use as a result of highway expenditure would benefit pro- ducers of transport equipment as well as the construction in- dustry. Closely related to the idea of indirect benefits is the concept of externalities. A well-educated population could result in the externalities of increased productivity and a more propitious climate for technical advancement. The externalities of a healthy population could be a longer and more productive life, and of an educated population, less so- cial delinquency and a more socially responsible electorate. Recently Charles E. McLure has tried to emphasize the pecuni- ary aspect of externalities in his study of how relative prod- uct and factor prices are affected by the public purchase of goods and the employment of factor services. His discussion of "expenditure incidence," which involves changes in the dis- tribution of income resulting from marginal differences in pri- vate and public spending patterns (as purchasing power is transferred from the private to the public sector), can be con- ceived as another example of how and why the concept of the di- rect or indirect benefits of externalities is important in the study of the redistributive impact of a fiscal system.3 “an”? 157 The question now is whether it is possible, in practice, to estimate all tangible as well as intangible ef- fects of government spending on direct and indirect benefici- aries. Unfortunately, given the present state of the art ofea benefit incidence study, it is very difficult, if not impos- sible, to go beyond the direct or primary benefits of govern- ment expenditures. As will be shown later, even an assessment of primary benefits is difficult. The full effects of govern- ment spending defy theoretical estimation at this point, much less quantitative measurement. It is possible, of course, to attack the problem of total effect estimation through cost- benefit analysis, but one must be willing to accept certain simplifying assumptions and subjective judgments in dealing with the following: the scope of possible effects; how long the effects will last; the opportunity cost of a particular activity; what discount rate to use; whether all possible costs and benefits have been considered; and so on. A full- scale cost benefit study of benefit incidence, apart from the above shortcomings also would be very costly. All in all, it seems more practical to evaluate only the direct, primary benefits. In doing so, all secondary and other effects as well as all externalities must be ruled out. This is the posi- tion adopted by most benefit incidence studies. The Measurement of Benefits Having selected the benefit approach and determined that only direct benefits are measurable, the next problem is 158 how to measure the benefits from public expenditures. If these are classified into three categories, namely, transfer expenditures, specific expenditures, and general expenditures, valuation of the first category poses little or no problem. If it is assumed that the benefits accruing to transfer re- cipients are not shifted to others, then the value of the benefits in money terms may be considered equivalent to the amount of such transfers. It is the specific and general ex- penditure categories that present problems. Specific government expenditures are expected to pro- vide benefits to readily identifiable groups. Funds spent on education should specifically benefit students in school; those spent on highways should benefit highway users and con- sumers of highway-transported products; subsidies for low- cost housing should benefit poor families; and so forth. How- ever, those goods and services are not necessarily private goods in their entirety, and thus valuation of benefits through the price mechanism and exclusion principle is not always pos- sible. For example, not all roads charge tolls, and some educa- tional services are free. A more manageable valuation of spe- cific benefits is possible if one is willing to make the impor- tant assumption that the total of benefits derived from a cer- tain expenditure program is equal to the total costs of that program. Under this assumption, the allocation of expenditure benefits is, in reality, the allocation of costs of public programs to expected primary beneficiaries. This "accounting 159 approach," called the cost incurred on behalf of" method by W. Irwin Gillespie and the "input approach" by G. S. Sahota4 implies that (l) the average cost of the provision of goods and services is constant, and (2) such provision is efficient in a Pareto Optimal sense: there is no overextension of ac- rivities and no waste.5 These assumptions are required to as- sure that marginal cost, average cost, and marginal benefit are all equal at an efficient equilibrium. For pure social goods provided by the government under such general expenditures as national defense, public adminis- tration, or diplomacy, the valuation problem is even more in- tractable because the true preferences of households are not known. A social good (or service) is consumed in equal amount by all, its enjoyment cannot be made subject to price payments, and no one can be excluded, even if he does not pay for it. Specifically, if the provision of a social good were to be financed through taxation, no one would reveal his true prefer- ence for fear that he would have to pay for the good and some- one else would get a free ride. Generally, since most of these benefits accrue to all families free of charge, families do not directly indicate the value they place on each good or service. Therefore, it is impossible to determine the total amount of benefits from each expenditure that should be added to the income of families. Although the provision of a social good could be de- termined through voting systems, it has been shown that there are no perfect systems.6 In fact, the valuation of public 160 goods is not possible unless one assumes that the consumer's preference function, or the social welfare function, or both, exist and are known. Even Paul A. Samuelson's celebrated theory of public good does not help because it does not ex- plain how public goods are determined or valued; it only states in a specific theoretical framework the condition under which a public good together with a private good are to be optimally or efficiently allocated.7 To overcome these difficulties, economists again re- sort to the accounting approach, where total benefits are as- sumed equal to total costs. As the marginal valuation of benefits of each household is still not known, certain utility functions (or allocation criteria) must be assumed. Although crude, there seems to be no better alternative, especially when empirical manageability is taken into account. As K. V. Green has said: "Given some plausible alternative models and our present state of knowledge about the demands of various groups for public services, the assumption that such benefits and costs are equal may be no worse than any other assumption."8 De Wulf has suggested the "behavioral approach," which also uses the valuation of benefits at production cost. However, after such benefits are allocated to different subgroups of the population, a further "subjective valuation" of the pre- sumed beneficiaries is made so as to estimate the real value of the benefits as closely as possible.9 But, unless some theoretical or operational framework is established for this subjective valuation, the results could be so diverse as to 161 render the expenditure incidence study totally unreliable. Despite the many shortcomings of the accounting approach, De Wulf admits that, in the absence of knowledge about the poli- tics of decision making, it is useful in the evaluation of publicly provided services to various subgroups of the popu- lation.10 Expenditure#Beneficiaries and the "Spendee" Concept The preceding section discussed how the benefits re- ceived by households from public expenditures are to be valued, a task which is unusually difficult because preference sched- ules are unknown. Recently a group of World Bank experts has attempted to substitute beneficiaries with the "spendee" concept, that is, households or groups within the population on whom government monies are spent. Emphasis no longer is placed on the value recipients attach to public benefits, but only on the magnitude of government spending for different activities and on whom it is helping.11 In a sense, this is an attractive solution to the re- vealed preference problem faced in expenditure incidence stud- ies. The study now becomes more manageable and less value laden since the focus shifts to who receives how much in terms of costs and away from benefits. For a study of the distributive impact of public expenditures alone, the spendee concept al- leviates many of the usual conceptual difficulties; the prob- lem becomes one of straightforward statistical estimation. But it does not offer a solution for a full fiscal incidence 162 study, where emphasis is placed on how much the government has helped in the distribution of income of households through public expenditures in exchange for what has been taken away from households in taxes. In other words, if taxes are as- sumed to have burdens which fall upon taxpaying households, then public expenditures similarly are assumed to generate benefits in varying degrees to the same households. The change from a beneficiary to a spendee concept thus does not completely solve the main problems of benefit incidence study.12 Practically speaking it seems that the valuation or measurement of the benefit of public expenditures must be carried out by the total benefits equal total costs method. Once the extent of benefits (costs) is known, the next ques- tion is how to allocate these benefits to households in dif- ferent income classes. For specific expenditures the bene- ficiary groups already have been decided upon; the remaining problem is to determine the bases upon which to distribute the benefits. Gillespie's study of the United States offers an example. The benefits of an expenditure on highways were first divided between highway users and nonusers. For non- users, cost was allocated according to the distribution of real property value. For users, the share of such costs was further divided between cars and trucks; that allocated to trucks was distributed proportionately to "consumers of trans- ported products," and that allocated to cars was similarly 13 distributed to "consumers of passenger travel." This is the method usually accepted in a highway benefit study. 163 For general expenditures, various studies have adopted one of several techniques. Benefits may be assumed to be dis- tributed either equally among households in all income classes (per capita or per household basis); proportionately on the basis of family income; according to certain utility functions, such as the ones used by Henry Aaron and Martin McGuire, and Shlomo Maital;14 or a combination of these bases may be used, for example, one-half distributed on a per capita basis, the other half on an income proportional basis. It must be noted that there is no definite rule specifying who the beneficiary group must be, or should be, for a certain expenditure cate- gory. Criteria vary according to the nature and extent of the given expenditure from one economic setting to another. The beneficiaries of highway expenditures in Gillespie's U. S. study, for example, might be different from those in Thailand. Also, the allocation bases may differ from country to country depending upon the availability of statistical data and other distributional information. A General Methodology The foregoing theoretical discussion has indicated the general direction this study on expenditure incidence in Thailand will take. The following specific methodology has been adopted: (1) With the exception of the transfer category for which the money flow method is considered more appropriate, the benefit approach will be used for most expenditures. 164 (2) Only direct, or primary benefits will be con- sidered in this study; all indirect benefits and externalities, either short or long run, are assumed constant or distribu- tionally neutral. (3) In general the accounting approach of benefit valuation will be used. It will be demonstrated during the course of this investigation why this technique is as accept- able as the more realistic behavioral method or cost-benefit analysis. Regarding the allocation of general expenditures, only one standard set of assumptions will be used to allocate such expenditures as defense, public administration, law en- forcement and justice. For reasons to be explained later, no alternative assumptions will be used to allocate general ex- penditures. (4) The beneficiary, as opposed to the spendee, con- cept will be used. A designated beneficiary may not always actually receive the benefits allocated to him, but it is as- sumed that under normal circumstances he would. (5) The procedure for allocating expenditure bene- fits to different income classes follows the pattern of tax burden allocation described in Chapter 3. First, the expendi- ture items are selected and classified into economic functions. Second, within each expenditure category a judgment is made as to which groups of households or which income classes are to receive the benefits and whether those benefits will remain with the recipient or be shifted to others. Third, the dis- tribution of these benefits by income classes is accomplished 165 using some of the allocation bases described in Chapter 3, such as the distribution of income, distribution of households, and distribution of household expenditures by income classes. In addition, a few other bases upon which to distribute these benefits will be used. Fourth, after all benefits are allo- cated to all income classes, the effective rates of these ex- penditure benefits relative to each corresponding income group will be calculated to determine whether the expenditure pat- tern is progressive (pro-rich) or regressive (pro-poor). The change in the pattern of income distribution after government expenditures also will be examined.15 Selection of Public Expenditures Public expenditures can be classified in several ways to suit several purposes. They can be categorized as consump- tion (current) expenditures and capital expenditures; or ex- haustive expenditures, essentially government purchases of goods and services and nonexhaustive expenditures, which cover such transfers as old-age pension and unemployment benefits. As indicated earlier, most studies classify public expendi- tures into specific or allocable, general or nonallocable, and transfer expenditures. In this study, a slightly different classification will be used. The specific/general/transfer breakdown will be retained, but this does not imply that specific expenditures are always allocable as pure private goods, and that general expenditures are always nonallocable as pure social goods. It will be seen later that some of the programs in the specific expenc genera ture p dence expend functi Specif. 166 expenditure category in Thailand are more in the nature of general than specific goods, and some of the general expendi- ture programs can indeed be allocated with reasonable confi- dence to a specific, identifiable income bracket. Basically, expenditures in Thailand will be grouped according to their functions or purposes. Six functional classifications are specified for all types of expenditures as follows: Group 1: Economic services a. Agriculture b. Power and Fuel c. Industries d. Transportation and Communication e. Other Economic Services Group 2: Educational Services a. Primary Education b. Secondary Education c. Higher Education d. Vocational Education and Other Group 3: Health and Social Welfare Services Group 4: General Services a. Defense b. Law Enforcement c. Public Administration d. Other General Services Group 5: Interest Payments on Public Debt These functional classifications conform closely with the method used by the National Statistical Office, but differ from curre: ed to ample crite found the a were Of t: are c benefi CludE ments On p1 and S and E tram 167 from the method used by the Bank of Thailand, which adds current and capital categories. This study initially intend- ed to follow the Bank's practice, but after checking the ex- amples of current and capital expenditures for the consistent criteria that distinguished one from the other, none were found. It seems that almost all expenditure categories under economic and educational services are listed under capital spending, and the rest under current spending. Therefore, the finer separation of expenditures into current and capital groupings did not seem to serve any useful purpose and only the functional classifications will be used here. Once the functional classifications were decided upon, the actual amounts of expenditures for each government agency were obtained from the Report of the Receipts and Outlays_gf the Kingdom of Thailand, published annually by the Department of the Comptroller General. The amounts used here, however, are only that portion of expenditures which is believed to benefit Thai residents; that benefitting nonresidents is ex- cluded. For example, portions of interest and principal pay- ments on foreign loans are subtracted from the total payments on public debt because, as transfers, their benefits fall di- rectly on foreign debt holders. The total adjusted amounts for each expenditure group and subgroup are shown in Table 4.1. Expenditure groups 1, 2, and 3 can generally be described as specific expenditures, and expenditure groups 4 and 5 as general expenditures and transfers, respectively. The table also shows that the level Table 4 168 Table 4. l—Total Adjusted Public Expeaditures of Thailand by Functimal Categariss, 1963 and 1969 (Mounts in Millions of Baht) 1963 1969 Emotional Categories Per- Per- Mount cent Anount cent Group 1: Economic Services 2,560.2 24.6 5,962.4 26.7 Agriculture 767.7 7.5 2,222.6 9.9 Power and Fuel 271.8 2.6 286.1 1.3 Industries 179.3 1.7 173.1 0.8 Transportation and Cannmication 1,079.3 10.4 2,959.8 13.2 Other Econcmic Services 253.1 2.4 320.8 1.4 Grow 2: Eflucational Services 1,777.5 17.0 3,674.3 16.4 Primary 1,024.7 . 9.8 1,997.9 8.9 Secondary 234.9 2.3 405.0 1.8 Higher 193.8 1.9 559.6 2.5 Vocational and Other Educatim 324.0 3.1 711.8 3.2 Grow 3: Health and Social Welfare 929.3 8.9 2,338.1 10.5 Grow 4: General Services 4,022.1 38.6 9,136.2 40.9 Defense 1,637.6 15.7 3,718.9 16.6 Law mfiorcanent 797.9 7.7 1,558.4 7.0 Public Adninistration 1,414.6 13.6 3,063.8 13.7 Other Gmeral Services 172.1 1.7 795.1 3.6 Grow 5: Payments on Public Debt 1,139.4 10.9 1,245.5 5.6 Total 100. 0 22, 356. S 100. 0 10.428.5 Sources: Thailand, Department of Ccmprtroller, Re Incomes and Outlays of the Kingdom of T t of the Receipts hail—and, 1963 and 1969 issues (Bangkok, 1965 and 1971) ; National Statistical Office, Statistical Yearbook of Thailand. of publ 1963 to culture ser but health . a1 serv. reductic other 56 Um next CldSSes. who the PeCted b 0n agric. C:Ommlll'lic: 59% portatic mately 7 were SP€ lOCated ments ' 169 of public spending increased by more than 100 percent from 1963 to 1969. Increased spending was most pronounced in agri- culture, transportation and communication, and defense. Les- ser but still substantial increased expenditures were made in health and welfare, higher education, and miscellaneous gener- al services. On the whole, educational services suffered some reduction, and the public debt services were reduced, while other services experienced some gains. Allocation of Public Expenditures Once the absolute amounts of expenditures are known, the next step is to allocate them to households by various classes. Each expenditure subgroup will be discussed as to who the direct beneficiaries are and on what basis these ex- pected benefits should be allocated. Group 1: Economic Services Expenditures for economic services include funds spent on agriculture, power and fuel, industries, transportation and communication, and others. Agriculture Expenditures on agriculture ranked second after trans- portation and communication in both 1963 and 1969. Approxi- mately 70 percent of total agricultural monies in both years were spent on irrigation projects, while the remainder was a1- 1ocated to the Ministry of Agriculture and its various depart- ments, such as Rice, Forestry, Livestock, Fishery, and Agric secto is a1; is all bracke proble. and ca; benefi1 Of eque with th be adOp in the beving i. ComPlet. 170 Agricultural Extension. Since it is assumed that the farming sector benefits directly from these expenditures, 50 percent is allocated equally to each rural household and 50 percent is allocated in direct proportion to the share of each income bracket in the rural family income. Allocating the benefits from irrigation creates some problems. Outlays on the construction of dams, reservoirs, and canals are capital spending which is expected to yield benefits in future years. The normal allocation method, that of equating the costs of capital expenditures in any one year with their benefits in the same year, which is the method to be adopted here, appears to violate common sense. For example, in the year when construction of a dam is underway, costs are being incurred, but the dam would not yield any benefit until completion, perhaps two or three years later. Therefore, it would seem unreasonable to match costs with benefits in the same year. However, one could argue that it is possible to impute the benefits for that year by discounting the stream of future benefits to the year in question, which could very well equal the costs of construction in that year. A more acceptable way of imputing the probable bene- fits from such investment expenditures as irrigation and other water resource development is through cost-benefit analy- sis. The use of this method in the case of water resources projects is perhaps the most established practice in all areas of devel tional p preparin method 1 cessful . tion. I. and publ Direct b! in farm : governme1 such as : of farm ] PurchaSe1 Public be and iHVe: mumity 1 effect 0: the eXPe the tOta and indi 171 of development program evaluation.16 Virtually all irriga- tional projects in Thailand use cost-benefit techniques in preparing feasibility reports for external borrowing. The method is universally used and is fashioned after its suc- cessful application by the United States Bureau of Reclama- tion. In Thailand, three kinds of benefits, direct, indirect and public, are normally evaluated in an irrigation project. Direct benefits from a new dam or reservoir include increases in farm property or farm income, investment in farms, and government revenues from land taxes and taxes on farm products, such as rice premiums. Indirect benefits incorporate sales of farm produce for local and nonlocal processing, and farm purchases for family living and production expenses. Finally, public benefits involve, for example, settlement, employment, and investment opportunities in the area, increases in com- munity living facilities and services, and a stabilization effect on the economy. After summing all the benefits over the expected life of the project (normally 25 to 30 years), the total is compared to the cost of the project, both direct and indirect. The resulting ratio usually is high enough to erase any doubt about the project's profitability. To give only two examples: the total benefit-cost ratio of the Kang Krachan Project (Rathburi Province in the Central Plain) was estimated at 13.3 to l, and the direct benefit-cost ratio of the Lam Ta Kong Storage Dam Project, in the northeastern prov- ince of Korat, was estimated at 9.1 to 1.17 cos1 eval irri the pecte that probl funct that 1 lems, tion, constr instit leads 1 and lor Crop in manY do tribUtII Call in EStimat pert in "The be tem ar inVOIVe Sh0u1d 172 It would appear more accurate to use the benefit- cost results from these feasibility reports as a basis for evaluation in this study. But, as the actual results of most irrigation projects have indicated, the benefit computed in the feasibility reports tends to overstate reality. The ex- pected benefits are computed generally on the assumption that technical and institutional factors will not create any problems in the actual construction of the project and in its functioning once completed. Experience has proved, however, that many irrigation projects suffer serious technical prob- lems, among them a water level that is too low for distribu- tion, unfinished or too shallow distributing canals, and poor construction due to the use of low—grade materials. On the institutional side, an inadequate control of most operations leads to large-scale corruption, causing tremendous waste and long delays. Moreover, many farmers fail to grow a second crop in the dry season, even when the water is available, and many do not exercise sufficient care in maintaining the dis- tributing canals in good working order. All these problems call into serious question the accuracy of benefit-cost ratios estimated on the order of nine or ten or more to one. One ex- pert in agricultural development in Thailand has commented: "The benefits from the uses of the present irrigation sys- tems are much lower than expected when compared to the costs involved; the efficiency of investment is far below what it should be."18 the v ing c more strat 173 The purpose of the foregoing has been to show that the valuation by existing cost-benefit analysis in a develop- ing country such as Thailand is by no means superior to other more qualitative approaches. The irrigation example demon- strates that equating total benefits to total costs in sub- sequent expenditure evaluation is actually quite reasonable. Since it can be conceived that some projects generate some- what more benefits than costs, while others generate less, the total benefits, overall, may reasonably be assumed to be equal to total costs. For the allocation of benefits from irrigation expendi- tures to various income groups, 70 percent is allocated to farmers according to their share in the distribution of rural family income. The reasoning for this is that the bigger the land holding and hence the higher the income position, the larger the benefits derived from water services. The remain- ing 30 percent is allocated to merchants, middlemen, trans- port operators, exporting companies, and all those who are associated with the process of transferring farm products from farm to market.19 As these groups are likely to reside in urban areas, the benefits are assumed to fall on urban households according to their shares in the distribution of urban family income. The same allocation rules are used for 1969 and 1963. Power a are sma expendi with e1 mission Authori 0f the « EXpendi1 househoj Authori1 t0 the I tric pov (most of the rema in PrOpc to hollse tramSPOI MiniStr and a f miniStr CUt has 174 Power and Fuel, and Industries The subcategories of power and fuel and industries are small in comparison to the others. Most power and fuel expenditures are allocated to government bodies associated with electricity generation, namely, the National Power Com- mission, the Provincial Electricity Authority, the Lignite Authority, the Metropolitan Electricity Authority, and two of the government-operated oil refineries. That portion of expenditures which clearly helps provide electricity for rural households, such as funds spent by the Provincial Electricity Authority, is assumed to benefit rural households according to the pattern of their income distribution. Since most elec- tric power expenditures aid urban more than rural households (most of the latter still do not have electricity service), the remaining benefits are distributed to households partly in proportion to their shares in the total income and the urban income. The benefits of refinery expenditures are distributed to households according to the patterns of expenditures on transport services, household operations, and total expendi- tures. Most industrial expenditures are allocated to the Ministry of Industries, some of its subsidiary departments, and a few state enterprises. The allocation of benefits from ministry services is quite difficult because there is no clear- cut basis for judgment. The rule adopted here is to allocate apprOI basis tures benef; tures food, TransE the la consis tion a are as the C1 benefi graph benefi the po catiOn proper; hold b with O lng ma pOrtiC SerVi\ trunk 175 approximately one-half the expenditures on a per household basis and the other half in proportion to income. Expendi- tures allocated for government enterprises are assumed to benefit households according to the patterns of their expendi- tures on the products of such enterprises, whether these be food, clothing, household goods, or others. Transportation and Communication Transportation and communication expenditures are the largest in the Expenditure Group 1. As expected, they consist of budgetary allocations to the Ministry of Communica- tion and its various departments. The services of the ministry are assumed to benefit every household equally, while those of the Civil Aviation Department (in 1969 only) are assumed to 20 Of the Post and Tele- benefit only the top income class. graph Department spending, 25 percent is believed to have benefited only the top income class, as this figure is roughly the portion of outlays on international postal and telecommuni- cation systems. Another 25 percent is distributed on an income proportional basis, and the remaining 50 percent on a per house- hold basis. Expenditures of the Port Authority, dealing mainly with overseas shipping, and of the Department of Harbour, deal- ing mainly with domestic water transport, are distributed pro- portionately according to household income shares and the pat- terns of household transport expenditures respectively. The services of the state railways are divided into passenger and trunk categories. Since about 53 percent of earnings in both 196 fro: utec ter: has: the asic give allc in 1 that Year be b 176 1963 and 1969 came from passenger services, and 47 percent from trunk services,21 53 percent of the benefits are distrib- uted to households on the household transport expenditure pat- tern basis and 47 percent on the total expenditure pattern basis. The expenditures of the Departmemt of Highways and the Department of Land Transport have specifically been set aside for discussion here so that special attention may be given to them. They constituted the single largest budgetary allocation of all other governmental departments in Thailand in 1969 and the second largest in 1963, obviously indicating that great emphasis was placed on highway construction in both years. It is necessary, therefore, that any benefit allocation be based on a careful study of the highway situation. Similar to expenditures on irrigation projects, funds for highway construction are investment expenditures, the bene- fits of which in any given year are difficult to measure. How- ever, using more or less the same methodology employed in deal- ing with agricultural expenditures, it is assumed that thelxnur- fits of highway spending in 1963 and 1969 are equal to its costs in the same period. This is not a major problem; more difficult is the distribution of these benefits among households of different income brackets. In his studies on highway expenditures in the United States and Canada, Gillespie assumes that expenditures are in- 22 curred on behalf of both users and nonusers of highways. Users are defined mainly as those who own and operate automobiles and user PIOE near use] and pros roac veys dice Way trax 177 and those who consume transported commodities, whereas non- users are those who benefit from the access facilities to their property and whose property increases in value as a result of nearby roads. Gillespie uses three methods to divide costs between users and nonusers and the cost share between passenger cars and trucks. For the former, he employs the relative use ap- proach: the distance traveled by vehicles on through traffic roads and local or access roads is compared through road sur- veys. The percentage share of through traffic road travel in- dicates the portion of highway expenditures that benefits high- way users, and the percentage share of local and access road travel the portion that benefits nonusers. Another method for separating user from nonuser bene- fits is the net earning credit approach. It is assumed that the frequency of use of primary and local roads in relation to their respective construction costs determines the benefits ac- cruing to road users and nonusers. Although the costs of con- struction and maintenance of through traffic roads are much higher than for access roads, the cost per vehicle mile travel- led is usually much lower for primary than for secondary roads. Compared to the relative use method, the earning credit method tends to yield higher benefits for nonusers. However, the re- sults of U. S. road studies, as cited by Gillespie, have shown that both methods give remarkably similar results. For the division between the benefits to'cars and.trucks, Gillespie uses the incremental cost method. This divides the cost 0: the f 0: vehicle vide a imagine cars a1 quire c are nee inches COStS c benefit States little much le Users i in Thai benefit muSt be coneent riVe Va rOad UQ the to‘ and 19 178 cost of road construction into "basic" and "specific" costs, the former being those necessary to provide a road for light vehicles, the latter being additional costs necessary to pro- vide a road for successively heavier vehicles. For example, imagine a road with a one-foot thick surface for use by both cars and trucks. It could be established that light cars re- quire only a four-inch surface; the additional eight inches are needed for the heavier trucks. The cost of the first four inches would therefore be spread over all vehicles, and the costs of the next eight inches over trucks of varying sizes. This brief summary indicates how the problem of highway benefits is dealt with in systems such as those in the United States and Canada, but unfortunately, all these methods have little applicability in Thailand. There, the road system is much less developed, the separation between road users and non- users is not practicable, and, most important there is no study in Thailand comparable to the one used by Gillespie toaallocate benefits to private cars and trucks. An entirely new approach must be adopted which eliminates the user/nonuser dichotomyanui concentrates mainly on the assumption that all households de- rive varying benefits from public highway expenditures. In Thailand it is possible to classify the number of road using vehicles into three main types: passenger cars, buses and taxies, and trucks. The prOportion of each type to the total number of vehicles is assumed to be the same in 1963 and 1969, that is, 60 percent trucks, 25 percent buses and 23 taxies, and 15 percent private passenger cars. It is then assumed that 15 percent of total highway expenditures in 1963 ; income sengei locate expend taxies of tru that beginn voliune Departr ducted senger Checkpc Data a: fur tru The Cla that or hOuSehC the fol eXampi¢ other road tl fQOd . cloth 1 179 1963 and 1969 are incurred on behalf of households in the top income bracket, since only this group can afford to own pas- senger cars. Twenty-five percent of highway spending is al- 1ocated to all households according to the pattern of their expenditures on transport services (those using buses and taxies). ' The remaining 60 percent is allocated to consumers of truck transported products. Information concerning goods that are transported by trucks nationwide is available only beginning in 1966, the first year a preliminary survey on the volume of road transport in Thailand was conducted by the Department of Land Transport. These national surveys, con- ducted each year since 1969, check all vehicles except pas- senger cars that pass through a number of randomly selected checkpoints during the two annual week-long survey periods. Data are gathered on points of departure, destination, and, for trucks, the commodity content of their hauls. It is this last information that is of interest here. The classification of transported commodities differs from that of commodity groups used in the 1962-1963 and 1968-1969 household expenditure surveys, but it is possible to rearrange the former classification to coincide with the latter. For example, rice, maize, vegetables) groceries, meat, fish, and other such products,which are classified separately in the road transport surveys,can be grouped under the category of food. Similarly, weaving materials can be grouped in the clothing category, and construction materials can be partly 180 assigned to the household operations group and partly to the transport and total expenditures categories. The next step is to determine the share of each commodity in the total trans- ported volume so that the portion of highway expenditures al- located to trucked transport may be similarly allocated. The best indicator as to the share of each transported commodity in total benefits is its total weight, which is equal to the number of trips multiplied by the weight of each trip. But since the incremental cost method does not enter into con- sideration in this study, the different weights of different trucks does not matter here. Instead, it is assumed that more benefits from highway expenditures should be imputed to the commodities which use the roads more often. In other words, only the number of trips or the number of trucks with different commodities passing through checkpoints will be used as a guide- line for allocating highway benefits. Table 4.2 shows the distribution of highway benefits assigned to trucked transport by allocation bases. According to the results of the above mentioned road survey, the largest percentage of commodities transported by trucks (21.7 percent) was of mixed types which could not be clearly assigned to any of the eight commodity groups. So, the benefits were allocated to households by the pattern of their total expenditures. Still, a large portion of truck-transported commodities was in the food and housing categories (20.3 and 19.1 percent reSpec- tively) of which the benefits were allocated to households ac- cording to the patterns of their expenditures on food and 181 Table 4 .2—Distribution of Highway Benefits Assigned to Trucked Transport, by Allocation Bases, 1963a and 1969 m . . 1...... Share teams... ocation Bases of Benefitsby (Million Baht) Each Allocatim Base 1963 1969 Food Expenditures 20.3 103.0 312.4 Housing Expenditures 19.1 96.9 294.1 Clothing Expenditures 1.2 6.4 19.3 Transport Ecpenditures 11.7 59.5 180.4 'Ibbacoo quaenditures 3.7 18.8 56.9 Total Expenditures 21.7 110.1 334.0 Total Non-Food Expenditures 7.2 36.7 111.2 Rural Income Distribution 12.2 62.0 188.1 Income of Rubber Growers 3.0 15.0 45.6 Total 100.0 508.4C 1,542.1d Source: Computed fran the 1969 results of the volune of land transport 3 urvey conducted annually by the Department of Land Transport. aDue to lack of data, the distribution of benefits in 1963 is assumed to have the same pattern as in 1969. bSee Appendix D for (htails and explanation of allocation bases. C'd'Ihese figures are the total anounts of highway benefits assigned to trucked transport in 1963 and 1969, respectively. 182 household operations, respectively. Other major commodity groups consisted of rice and other farm products, and fuel. Based on Table 4.2, a substantial amount of highway benefits could be distributed fairly easily and objectively. Other Economic Services Major expenditure items assigned to the "other" eco- nomic services group include expenditures of the office of the Under-Secretary of the Ministry of National Development, the Department of Soil Development, the Department of Land Co-operatives, and the Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural Co-operatives (for 1969 only). As most of these expenditures tend to benefit the farming sector, they are allocated mainly according to the share of rural households in the rural in- come distribution. Group 2: Educational Services As a group, educational expenditures accounted for less than 20 percent of total expenditures in 1963 and 1969. Among the four subgroups--primary, secondary, higher, voca- tional and other-~primary education received the highest share, with vocational and other education a distant second. In Thai- land, primary education is compulsory for seven years (Prathom l to Prathom 7). Secondary education occupies the next five years of a student's life (Mor Sor l to Mor Sor 5). The stu- dent then may go on to college, where he normally spends four years to obtain a bachelor's degree. The above is what gener- ally is referred to as an "academic" line of schooling. There 183 is also "vocational" schooling from the secondary through college levels. Most public primary schools are administered by the Provincial Administration Organization in each province under the academic supervision of the Ministry of Education and with financial support from the Ministry of Interior. Some local municipalities also operate their own public primary schools separately. Public secondary and vocational education are generally operated and administered completely by the Ministry of Education. All universities were under the control of the Office of the Prime Minister before 1972, at which time a special Bureau of State Universities was established. The functioning of the educational system in Thailand is not of interest here. What is of concern is to whose bene- fit the educational expenditures should be allocated. Accord- ing to the benefit principle adopted in this study, children attending school and their parents, not the teaching profes- sion, are the proper beneficiaries of public educational spending. In his study of educational benefits in the United States and Canada, where statistical sources usually are among the best, Gillespie was able to develop two allocation formu- las: the distribution of school children under 16 years of age by parental income class, and the distribution of univer- sity students by parental income class. The first of these formulas is obviously inadequate because it includes pre- school children and excludes older students still attending secondary schools. However, Gillespie pointed out that no 184 better allocation alternative was available.24 Primary Education In Thailand statistics similar to the above do not exist. Until there is a household survey to determine the number of children in school by class of parental income, the only way to allocate the educational benefits of primary and secondary education is to make reasonable but arbitrary as- sumptions. Since primary education is compulsory and the government must provide schooling for every child, it would appear that primary schooling is somewhat similar to a public good, and every family benefits equally, and no family can be excluded. But to allocate actual primary education expendi- tures equally on a per household basis would be incorrect for two reasons: (1) expenditure per pupil is greater for schools in urban than in rural areas, and (2) households in lower in- come brackets often cannot afford to permit children to at- tend school all day, or even to attend at all, since they can- not afford books and clothing and/or the children are needed for farm work at a very early age. It is evident therefore, that the income position of households influences who receives educational benefits. With this in mind, one-half of primary education expenditures is arbitrarily allocated on a per house- hold basis for both 1963 and 1969, and the other half in pro- portion to income. 185 Secondary Education Relatively few Thai students who finish primary school continue on to the secondary level. In 1963, of all students attending public primary and secondary schools throughout the country, 96 percent were enrolled in primary schools and only 4 percent in secondary schools.25 In 1969, these percentage shares remained the same.26 The problem may lie either on the demand or the supply side, that is, either parents cannot afford to send their children to secondary schools, or sec- ondary and higher educational facilities are lacking or inade- quate, or both. It is believed, however, that the demand out- weighs the supply factor. If so, then a family's income posi- tion plays a significant role in determining the educational future of children beyond the primary stage. It is assumed, then, that the benefits of secondary education expenditures should be distributed to families according to their share in the distribution of family income. Admittedly, this is not the best formula, but neither is it unreasonable nor implausi- ble. Higher Education In 1968 the National Educational Council of Thailand conducted a survey of the cost of living of university stu- dents.27 It originally was intended that at least one ques- tion would inquire about the income of the student's parents. For some unexplained reason, this question was excluded from the actual survey. 186 Fortunately, there is another source of information, albeit a limited one, on the income distribution of parents whose children are enrolled in universities. These data, classified into 11 income brackets, can be found in a publica- tion of Thammasat University, General Facts About First-Year Students at Thammasat University, 1972-1973. Since no similar information exists for other institutions, the pattern des- cribed for Thammasat University is used as representative of all university students. There are strong arguments in sup- port of this decision. First, the data for both 1972 and 1973 are quite similar (a correlation coefficient of .9907), imply- ing that students from the same income classes entered Tham— masat University in these two years. Second, Thammasat Uni- versity may be considered typical of other universities; there is no apparent reason to think that the university's policy is biased in favor of or against any classes of households or stu- dents, or that any specific groups of students tend to enroll there more than at any other institution. Therefore, the aver- age income distribution of parents of first-year Thammasat Uni- versity students in 1972 and 1973 is used as the allocation formula for higher education expenditures in both 1963 and 1969. Vocational and Other Educational Services Most vocational education expenditures are allocated to households in the same manner as secondary school expendi- tures. The notable exception is expenditures by the Department of Teacher Training, which are allocated on the same basis as primary education benefits (since most prospective teachers 187 will be employed in primary schools). For other educational services, 50 percent of expenditures on educational administra- tion, educational techniques, and fine arts are arbitrarily al- located to households on a per household basis, and the other 50 percent proportional to income. Expenditures on national research are allocated to all households equally. Group 3: Health and Social Welfare Services Expenditures in the health and social welfare category consist mainly of budgetary allocations to the Ministry of Public Health, Department of Public Welfare, Department of Public Works, Department of Community Development, Accelerated Rural Development Programs, and the Government Pension Plan. The Ministry of Public Health and its two largest departments, Health and Medicine, are responsible nationwide for the opera- tion of most public hospitals and preventative medical meas- ures such as vaccinations and health education. Thailand has no health insurance system, but the costs of public hospitali- zation and other medical services are low, and poor families often receive various treatments free of charge. The main problem, however, lies in insufficient medical facilities, especially the low number of hospitals, health clinics and doctors. _ An ideal way to account for the benefits received by various households from public health expenditures would be to keep records of the income of those who come for medical services and the estimated share of the costs of such services 188 for each income class. Unfortunately, such data are not available, and it is necessary to make an arbitrary assump- tion. Since households in lower income brackets often re- ceive free or less expensive medical services than do those in higher income brackets, it is reasonable to assume thattflua benefits are distributed according to the share of the pp- ciprocal of household income. In other words, expenditures are allocated in such a way that the poorer the household, the greater the benefits received. On the public welfare side, the Department of Public Welfare helps find jobs for the unemployed, raises orphans, cares for the elderly, gives temporary relief to households during natural disasters, and so forth. Similar to health expenses, these public welfare expenditures are allocated to families according to the distribution of the reciprocals of their income. Government pensions, also included in this expenditure category, are allocated to government employees using the distribution of civilian officials in 1963 and 1969. Oddly enough, these pensions are the only explicit public transfers in the entire range of government spending. Services of the Department of Public Works in the area of public utility construction are assumed to benefit mainly urban households and are distributed according to the distribution of urban income. On the other hand, services of the Department of Community Development and the Office of the Accelerated Rural Development Programs benefit rural house- holds almost exclusively. Their expenditures are thus 189 allocated to those households according to the share of each income class in the distribution of rural income. In all, public expenditures in the health and social welfare category are relatively small compared to others. It is somewhat odd that, although most Thais are generally poor, the government is least active in the area of public transfers, from which poor households in need of assistance could benefit most directly. Group 4: General Services Expenditures in the general services group-—defense, public administration, justice, and law enforcement--have been variously called general, nonallocable, and public goods expenditures. Having established that all individuals or households derive equal benefit from such expenditures, and that consumption by one person has no effect on the consump- tion of another, most researchers allocate benefits from these general expenditures equally to every individual or household. However, it increasingly has become necessary to question the wisdom of such a practice; what is theoretically sound may not be plausible or valid in reality. The conventional expenditure incidence study frequently lumps all general expenditures into one group and then allocates them to individuals or households using different criteria. Since there is no definite set of guidelines, several alterna- tive assumptions are necessary. However, if one looks closely into the disaggregated details of a general budget, it can be 190 seen that some of the generally conceived expenditures provide positive benefits to identifiable groups. At least they are not entirely "unallocable" as usually assumed.28 Because few funds fall into this category, and because the majority of general expenditures may be truly general or nonallocable, a compromised approach is adOpted in this study. Rather than lump all such expenditures and use alternative allocative as- sumptions, attempts are made to disaggregate them to the ex- tent practicable so that a reasonable rule may be applied to each subgroup. The following section will discuss, in turn, the allocation rules of expenditures on defense, law enforce- ment, public administration, and other miscellaneous public activities. Defense Being predominantly a military-controlled country, Thailand Spends a great deal on defense. The budgetary alloca- tions to the Ministry of Defense accounted for almost 16 percent of the total budget in 1963 and almost 17 percent in 1969. Unlike expenditures by other government organizations, defense spending is shrouded in secrecy; no details are pub- lished, especially concerning a quite substantial portion set aside for "secret services.f A detailed examination of defense spending is thus impossible and one must rely only on the conceptual characteristics of defense benefits. Theoretically, national defense is often cited as a good example of a pure public good; it is purported to 191 protect equally the life and property of every citizen. This is a correct theoretical conclusion, but it also could be ar- gued that the higher the income or wealth status of an indi- vidual or family the greater is his desire to protect it. In short, the wealthier a person is, the more he stands to lose in the event of invasion and conquest, and consequently the more he appreciates protection from the defense system.29 Therefore, rather than allocate benefits from defense spending on a per capita or per household basis, one could allocatetflmmi according to the share of each individual or household in the distribution of income (or wealth if the data are available). Such is the allocation formula adopted in this study. In con- trast to the conventional per capita allocation, the propor- tional allocation rule is gaining wide acceptability. A. C. Harberger, for example, has said: There are a great many government outlays for general purposes (administration, the courts, national defense) whose assignments as benefits to particular income groups is necessarily quite arbitrary. The notion that these benefits are roughly proportional to income and/or wealth, however, seems at least to be a plausible approximation.30 Law Enforcement Expenditures in the law enforcement category can be divided into two subgroups, justice and police. For the jus- tice system (Ministry of Justice, Department of Public Prose- cution, and Department of Correction), it is reasoned that, as every person or household should be equally served by the due process of the law, benefits should be distributed equally 192 to all individuals or households. This allocation rule is rather straightforward and quite obvious. The same cannot be said for police expenditures, which rank very high among major government outlays. It is true that the strength of police forces is proportionately much greater in urban and metropolitan than in rural areas. It is also true that special branches, such as traffic, fire, and highway police are oriented toward serving individuals or house- holds in central cities or towns which are mainly in the higher income brackets. Consequently, it would be incorrect to assume that every household in the nation enjoys the same service from police operations. Rather, it would be more appropriate to di- vide the police budget in half and distribute the first half to households on a per household basis and the other half to .households on an income proportional basis. This formula is used here. Public Administration Expenditures of government organizations which have not been classified previously are here classified as public administration expenditures. These are quite large, amounting to almost 14 percent of total expenditures in Thailand in 1963 and 1969. Two types of government organizations are included in this category: those constituting general bureaucratic ad- ministration, such as the Department of Local Government, Ministry of Finance, Department of Land, and Ministry of Eco- nomic Affairs, and those that deal with other government bodies 193 or the general affairs of the state, such as the Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Department of Technical and Economic Coopera- tion, State Service Commission, and Office of Government Audit. Normally one would allocate public administration ex- penditures on an equal per capita or per household basis be- cause they are aimed at satisfying social wants. Neverthe- less, it could be argued strongly that in Thailand, where the administrative system is very centralized, the effects of general government are more likely to be felt in urban than in rural areas. It is more correct, therefore, to allocate benefits according to an arbitrary 75—25 percent rule; 75 per- cent of the bulk of public administration expenditures is dis- tributed to each household equally, and the other 25 percent on an income proportional basis. A portion of these expendi- tures primarily benefit government officials, for example, the Government Official Assistance Fund and government scholarships. This portion is distributed to official households according to their shares in the income distribution of government of- ficials. Other Miscellaneous Expenditures Some expenditures are set aside for the government's Reserve Fund, which is used during natural disasters or for augmenting certain regional development projects which unex- pectedly run short of funds. Since no details are given as to how the Reserve Fund is spent, it is allocated equally among households. 194 Group 5: Interest Payments on the Public Debt.31 The long-standing controversy as to who should benefit from interest payments on the public debt has yet to be de- cided. There are various ways to look at the nature of public debt and the effects of its interest payments.32 First, in a classical setting, where full employment is assumed, interest payments can be construed as the cost or factor return incurred by the government in providing cer- tain goods or services through loan finance. If this view is adopted, then the benefits of interest payments should be al- located to families in proportion to their consumption of debt-financed goods and services. But since government loans are not always tied to provision of specific goods and ser- vices, it is quite impossible to determine who benefits. Even when a project is known to be specifically financed by a cer- tain loan, it still may be very difficult to estimate the pro- portion of goods and services consumed by families in each in- come class. Second, in a less than full employment setting, the creation and liquidation of public debt is seen as a fiscal compensatory action of the government. Assuming the government could monetize the debt if it so wished, its decision not to do so could be considered the desire of the government to sup- press an inflationary increase in private expenditures. In other words, interest payments can be seen as the price paid for the purchase of nonspending or illiquidity. If this view is adopted, the beneficiaries of such payments would be those 195 affected in one way or another by liquidity control, something very hard to pinpoint, of course. As McLure has pointed out, allocating the true benefits of buying illiquidity and reduc- ing aggregate demand is a complex question, and the answer is far from clear.33 Third, interest payments on public debt can be con- ceived simply as transfer payments which serve to redistribute income in the course of providing loan-financed goods and ser- vices. It is reasoned that, since taxes are levied to pay for interest payments on public debt, and if the distribution of tax payments by income classes is not identical with the dis- tribution of interest payments, there will be a redistribution of income among families. To treat these payments as transfers is also consistent with the general practice of national income accounting. If this View is adopted, then interest charges should be allocated to families that receive the payments. Despite McLure's insistence that allocating benefits of interest payments to holders of the public debt makes no sense,34 this approach offers the most practical way to trace the beneficiaries, and it has been adopted by most researchers 35 For lack of a better alternative, on expenditure incidence. this approach also is adopted here. The next immediate question is: On what basis should these interest payments of the Thai government be allocated to which recipients? There are four main groups of domestic debt holders: the Bank of Thailand, Government Savings Bank, commercial banks, and other financial institutions and domestic 196 sectors. Of these, the commercial banks and other financial institutions combined held about 38.0 percent and 38.8 percent of the domestic debt in 1963 and 1969, respectively: the share of the Bank of Thailand was 41.4 percent and 31.4 per- cent, and that of the Government Savings Bank 18.5 percent and 29.5 percent.36 A very small share was also held by the national Exchange Equalization Fund. Therefore, about 40 per- cent of the benefits from interest payments accrued to share- holders of commercial banks and other financial institutions, and they are likely to represent only from the top income bracket. Small savers in the lower income groups who normally save with the Government Savings Bank are quite numerous, but their share of benefits is small compared to major corporate savers. As a result, and due to a lack of information on the distribution of interest payments by income classes, one-half of interest payments on public debt for 1963 and 1969 are al- located entirely to the top income group, and the other half is allocated to all families in proportion to their share in total income. Empirical Results of Expenditure Analysis The procedure for estimating expenditure incidence is identical to that used in estimating tax incidence in Chapter 3. After deciding upon criteria for allocating all public ex- penditures disaggregated down to departmental levels, the ex- penditures are distributed to various income brackets based on the chosen criteria. The basic results, as shown in Tables 197 4.3 and 4.4, are the absolute amounts of expenditure benefits by income classes, by five main groups of expenditures and their related subgroups. As in Chapter 3, these basic results may be presented in two ways: effective expenditure rates by absolute income levels using both money income and adjusted income as bases, and the change in the pattern of income dis- tribution as a result of public expenditures (the so-called post-benefit income distribution) and its related change in terms of Gini concentration ratios. Before examining the empirical results, the reader must be cautioned about the nature and procedure of this ex- penditure incidence study. First, the estimates of absolute benefits by income classes are exactly that: estimates. The fact that they are quantitatively stated should not mislead one into thinking that they are the exact "benefits" accruing to different income classes. The beneficiaries are families on whose behalf the costs of public expenditures are incurred, and some benefit allocation criteria are quite arbitrary owing to various conceptual and statistical difficulties. Moreover, these families have only one characteristic in common, their income level; the estimates say nothing about such interfamily differences as the size of the household, age and education of heads of households, their occupations, and so on. Second, when the average expenditure benefits per family are obtained by dividing the class benefits by the number of families in that income class, the result is the benefits of a typical or representative family only. In reality, each family 198 mp2}: «583 ASS; immim 0.8m; fimmms A38. :2; 98A. mi TR: was 0.3. noon 33.3 no Bow—son as: 93 93 8mm hmm mam 850 33; ~63 and «SH ~§~ has. Eggnog ofifio has A32 88 1162 on: with uogmonomfi 33 p.53 mém NJ: as? imam hm: 8.8an Name; mama :18 as? The ads; 8088 A898 mama Emma home as». 32: 3.2 magnum momma: a £891 oémm 9% 8mm 3K 1.4m was go pom 83388 114.3 1:3 3: «.1 To as 88E 38 was so... C.3 Tam mom @888 3.8; TEN mom ~68 do: 92... go met; 3% as: seam oém «a: moonsom 83888 dmmm ado 98 4.8 TS «.2. 850 mas; has he: SEN an: ofim ooflfluonmfih. m . as m .2 A. 3 o .3 A Am 98 moehmoofi EAR 93 man 9: Tom mam Hon...— 8... .858 to: some m .21 can he: 92A 83883 Teams 1152. TEN 31$ imam spam «pogo oeaSom 8820 .88 Ba 118.2 an: 8a.... 8?». s I s I s I. s A2 8o 3 8o 3 So a 8a m .88: noenooouno 8353a Bone moonSo 8.85 Ann—om mo msonflnz 5 3595. mom." 63630 9505 an .mousuflofimxm mo momma >9 .muflmoswm gagfillmé manna 199 m.omm.- A.~mo.m ~.oH¢.A m.mm~.a A.~me.~ ~.~am.~ a.mmo.~ m.m~o.~ Among 888A ~80. ~.~a 88 8B 88 83 88 88 838 no 328 A68 843 82 83. 82. ~82 88A 88A 850 888m 88s 88: 88~ 88m 8:; 88m 5.8m. 881...me 833 888A ~.~$ 88 8m: ~84 83~ ~.:.~ ~.$~ ufihonflé 33 m.me~.~ m.msm.a m.am~ m.oom m.mqm ~.mmm ~.asm o.mme omooumo ~.ome.m A.~mm.m m.smm A.o~s m.oaa m.AmH.H ~.omm.H m.m~o.a nooeonom Hoooooo A88~ ~48 88~ 88~ 88~ ~48 82H 88~ 8088 2882 a 5A8: 8A: 82... 83 8mm 88 88 ~.$ m8 ammo o8 88382, 8.8 ~88 8- 8- 88 88 8~ m.~ 888 88v ~48 8R ~.~m 85 82 8R #2 88.88 888A 89% En: ~83 8A3 88~ 88m 88~ Esp 8453 888; H.8~ 8mm~ 8on 83. 85. 83m 888m A8388 :8 8H: 8- 88 8% 88 85 A.m~ go 8am8~ 888A 88A 88~ 88~ 88~ 8B~ 848 8888889 35 88 8m 82 82 83 83 8: 8883 A88 82: 88 8m~ 88 8mm 8:. 83 Anon o8 838 o . -~.~ 888 a . 3H m .2: m .o- A. A8 a .8~ 8 «S 83838 888m 888~ 8.8 88 :8 ~58 ~48 88m 8338 8888 momnflo 826 o8 885 88: 883 88m 88m 88m A2 888 .888 -882 -88m $86 -88». ~85 Gnome mommflo 8.85 mowuomoumu maven—59$ 38mm m0 9338. 5 Boonie mood momma-HO mEoQoH an. 683%? NO woman. an .Bflmocwm managinvé manna. 200 within the same income bracket receives different benefits. For example, if one family has children in public schools or universities and another family has none, the benefits from educational expenditures clearly would fall on the first fami- ly at the expense of the second. Furthermore, one family may pay taxes, while another family successfully manages to evade them. These discrepancies must be assumed negligible or to cancel each other out for manageability in research. Third, the ostensibly precise nature of the effective expenditure rates must not be overemphasized. Such rates are merely the result of mathematical division and should be taken as a general approximation of how much is added to original family income as a result of public expenditures. Effective Expenditure Rates by Income Classes When the total income of each income bracket is used to divide each corresponding amount of expenditure benefits, as shown in Tables 4.3 and 4.4, the effective expenditure rates are obtained. Tables 4.5 to 4.8 show these effective expenditure rates based on money and adjusted income, respec- tively. For all income classes, the benefits are classified by functional categories of expenditures. As can be seen from Tables 4.3 and 4.4, the absolute amounts of expenditure benefits accruing to each income class are not very informative, apart from the noticeable fact that the top income group also receives the highest share of bene- fits. 201 ~.8 88 88 8- ~4~ 88 H38. 8m 80 8A 8A 8A 8A 88 33:3 :0 magma 8o 80 ~.o 80 8o 8A .850 3. 8A 8~ 8m 8m 83 893% 338 8~ AA 8H 8H 8m 8... ”8.8885 33 8s 8s 8v 83. 8s 81‘ 88mg 8: Es 8m 8: 82 8s~ noonnom 8.88m ~.~ 8A 8... a m 8~ in 833.38 8883 o 588 80 8o 80 8o A; 5H 880 o8 888803 8a «4 8o ~.o u u 888 ho ho to To To To E88 8... EA H.~ 8~ A m 81. goo ~.m 8s 8s m a 8m «8 833.38 H8888 To 8o To 8o 80 A; 850 on 8m 8~ 8~ 8m 81. 5388888. 8o 8° 8° 8° 8a A; 88835 8a 8o 80 8o 8o 8o A8...— 98 838 m.~ e4 8A m.~ 8~ 8a 85883 8A To .8 8o ms 8: 80858 3.588 888 .36 pa 88S 88: 88m 88m s s s s A2 .8 3 $8 ~A 18 o 18 m n85 88888 magmas Aunmmv mommmao 9:85 mos: so 033 .mommmau 8505 an .mousuflosmmxm mo monks an .8umm ousuwocomonm 938mmmlmé 83mm. A8omoooono$ $2 .885 Table 4.6—Effective Ebcperditure Rates, by types of Ebcpenditures, by Inccme Classes, Based on Adjusted Income, 1963 (Percmtages) Incone Classes (Baht) 202 Hg m OVNVM m MMNV N H I-INwN m m o o o o o o o o c o o o o o o o o a o HUI m HCCHO N H000 H L“ Nv-Io-IO H 00 4:6 H Fl 0 ch”! 88 H I‘Q‘Hgm N CDMFM m I" mxom' N O o o g o o o o o o o m‘ m OOOHO N 0000 O m NCO m 2 Hg I 88 N OVNMM O HMNQ‘ m \D VQMI—I m m o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 cm "I HOOP-IO N u—looo H V Net-IO o f: ~§ NI‘ I-II-l I 83: m I—IQ‘NNQ‘ v-I WWII-1Q: m m ”@O‘N w m 0 O O O Q o O o o 0 90‘ m v-IOCI—IO N H000 H m Nev—Io O 2 ‘§ EDI—I r-l I om Ln MMMMQ- m \Dm In C CD OMNM I‘ V‘ °¢ o o o o o o o o o' o o o o o o o o 0 cm W HOOHO N HO 0 H In NI—INO O 2 s 5 mm C 8 Q‘ Nmmem I‘ ON'LO ON 0‘ Vle-n ln Q‘ 0 0 I o o O o O o 0 o o o o O o o 0 (r; m HOOP-Io N No C O \O HHMO o : Ebcpefliuire Categories Economic Services Power and Fuel Agriculture IndLstries Transportation Other Educational Services Vocational and Other Secondary Higher Health & Welfare Services General Service Public ministration Law Ehforcenent Other Defense Payments on Prblic Debt ‘Ibtal Table 4. 7-Effective Expenditure Rates, by Types of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on mney Insane, 1969 (Percentages) Income Classes (Baht) 203 m 38 N Q'Q'Mkoln I‘ Hva-l \D H mfi‘hN m ‘0 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o g 0‘ MOCQ‘O In ”OCH "3 V mNQ‘l-I H a PI H U 0 8% In l‘fl'maflm 0‘ O‘Dva‘ ln 0 qu'Q‘ a) I‘ o o o o o o o o o o o o o c o o o o 0 § w NOOQ‘O v NOo-lo N O Inf-INC N m mg H N H I 00‘ 8% m mmNQLn (n WWI-no In 0‘ met-Io C N o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o ‘\ m moomo Q‘ Noel—I Ln N LnNQ'O-I H N In" H ('5 HF! I ca 88 m mle-Im o mWQ'v-I H I‘ ml-‘IQC o W o o o o o o o o o o o o o g o o o o o \s m MCOQ'O tn NCOv-I In M vao-l PI 00 NV H m .4.-I I 00‘ 00‘ N mmNI-‘IW M NKDMF‘I O Q‘ mmmm o m cos 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o ~~ OI mcoqo l-n MOOH Ln Ln LannI-I H In G‘F‘I H m ._. ég“ o NmNMF o O‘WMN I.“ m ml-Ilnafl o I‘ o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o I o o 00‘ o Q'oovo \D MCOH m I‘ lnMIOI-I PI I‘ ~~ PI H M W” I CO‘ 0‘ ommmm ‘0 mm In C W mwv—If-‘I O 0 CG 0 o o o o o o 0 0| 0 o 0 o o o o o o oa‘ o moofi'o I‘ \06 H m N mfi‘mm H I.“ ~ ~ H N Q mm 50 o o wawo In mm m o m ml-‘IO‘I‘ o O‘ o o o o o o o u 0 0| I g o o o o o o o g~ In Noemi-I Q‘ Ho N H Q‘ “30°F H In m H H H H V‘ F'IN m Expenditure Categories ervices Emmmic S Agriculture PowerandFuel Industries Transportation Other Edmational Services Higher vocational am! Other Health & Welfare Services ervices General S Defense ation law Enforcement Ptblic Adnin ' Payments on Ptblic Debt Total Table 4.8-Effective Expenditure Rates, by ‘Iypes of Expenditures, by Income Classes, Based on Adjusted Incane, 1969 (Percentages) Income Classes (Baht) 204 g H Ian—ION In VMQ‘In \0 v \Dl—Il—IID 0‘ V o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o c H U o’d 88 H MNHMN Q‘ mMI‘Q' N co mhr-IN M I‘ o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o I o o 0 ~ V‘ HOONO N COCO H V NOu—(O H m m'E v—l ._. (U I 00‘ O . . O . O . . . C O O O C . O . O . ~‘ fi' l—IOONO N H000 N \D MHNC 0 ID In“ H F'IF-I I 00‘ 88 In mNu-h-lm In VMNID ID as O‘l-IQ'In In C o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o ~~ Q‘ HOONO N Hooo N IO NHNO o I‘ NV v-I HI—I I 88 N I‘Nv-IO‘M Q. mMNIn m 0 \DNIOID Q q a o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o g o o 00‘ Q‘ HOOP-IO N Hooo N I‘ NHNO O S s s ¢H v-I ég“ I-I [\NHmm In WWII-(In Q‘ f—I Q'mmm v Q' o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 cm Q‘ HOOP-Io N HOOD r-| I‘ (Vt-INC 0 I3 s s ID“ I 00‘ m I‘Nl—Imm IO CNN In C m CIDF'If-I m In cm 0 o o o o o o 0 0| 0 o o o I o o o 0 cm (’3 HOOHO N HO o H I‘ Nl—IMH O a ~ ~ MID o o H ONNan 0 mm ID 0 m \DmmF-I m I‘ o o o o o o o o 0 0' o o o o o o o o 0 ~ Q' NOOF‘IO Q mo 0 m N I-INInN O m m H N Expenditure Categories Economic Services Agriculture PowerandFuel Industries Transportation Educational Services Health & Welfare Services General Services Law Enforcement Public Administration Defense Payments on Public Debt Total 205 When expressed in terms of effective rates, the impact of pub- lic expenditures upon the income distribution of households in 1963 and 1969 becomes clearer. Using money income as the base, the lowest income bracket clearly received the highest share of benefits from public expenditures in both years. The ef- fective expenditure rates for the lowest,income group were 49.8 percent and 85.9 percent in 1963 and 1969, respectively, compared to rates of 26.8 percent and 28.7 percent for the highest income group in the same years. The effective rates were much higher in 1969 than in 1963, meaning, in part, that the benefits accruing to the low- est income group were much greater in 1969 than in 1963. This pattern also applies to the top income class. As a matter of fact, the effective expenditure rates across the entire in- come range improved in 1969 over 1963, meaning essentially that during these six years the expenditure benefits for all income groups increased faster than their money income, and all clas- ses received relatively higher gains from public spending in 1969 than in 1963. When the effective expenditure rates are computed using adjusted income as the base, the results are understandably lower than the rates based on money income. The change, of course, reflects the pattern of adjusted income distribution vis-a-vis money income distribution in that the effective rates of the lower income groups, particularly the two lowest ones, are now only slightly larger than those of the higher income groups. As indicated in Chapter 2, this is because, in the 206 adjusted income as compared to the money income distribution, the income positions of the lower brackets increase relatively more than those of the higher brackets. This change seems to have "flattened out" the distribution of effective expenditure rates across income classes from the lowest to the highest. The effective expenditure rates from the bottom income bracket is now shown to have been 14.4 percent and 23.7 percent in.l963 and 1969 respectively, whereas the corresponding effective:rates for the top income bracket are 28.7 percent and 13.0 percent. The distribution of effective expenditure rates by in- come classes in 1963 and 1969 using both money income and ad— justed income as bases can be depicted graphically. This is shown in Figures 4.1 and 4.2. It can be seen that, on a money income base, the income distributional effects of public ex- penditures were generally regressive or pro-poor in both years (and more so in 1969, as noted above). But the degree of re- gressivity falls off rapidly after the first income bracket and remains only slightly regressive for the rest of the in- come classes. The exception is 1963, when the effective rates turn slightly progressive at the highest income bracket. On an adjusted income base, the pattern of effective rates seems to have levelled off considerably, as noted earlier. The gen- eral pattern could not now be called clearly regressive, be- cause there is some fluctuation in the middle income range in both years. Similar to the treatment on the tax side, if one re- gresses these effective expenditure rates on their respective 207 area on. new“ .nonnaao o-oocH an .vnoocm 50:0: :0 con-m uovum ounaauconxm o>aaoommmuua.: ouswuh 3.3 no 8:323 mooaqao ouoocH a 3 2 a s n 0 ON om ll Aacoouomv moons Saigon—nu u>uuooumm 208 mow" use mead .uomuqao onoocm an .o-oocH coauzfiu< no conga noun: ounpavconxm o>uaoommmno~.a ousmuh Aandm mo nusuusonav nounaao osoocH | l“||'ll|l‘||'ll'l'l I -'|lil'|'|'l- I _I"'-""""' $2 8.: .: ........ fom vow A v Avcouuomv moan: ounaucnonxm o>uvoouum 209 average annual income levels using the ordinary least-square method, the resulting slope of the regression curve could be used to roughly indicate the degree of regressivity of the expenditure system. As shown in Table 4.9, the slopes of the regression curves that indicated the pattern of the.l963 effective expen- diture rates based on money and adjusted income are estimated at -.369 and -.026, respectively. For 1969, the corresponding slopes are -.935 and -.076. This generally confirms the con- clusion that on a money income base the expenditure rate pat- tern is slightly regressive, but on an adjusted income base it is barely regressive, so that for all practical purposes it may be regarded as proportional (particularly for 1963). The detail of effective expenditure rates by type of expenditures also may be found in Tables 4.5 ‘U3 4.8. On the average, across income classes, in 1963 and 1969, the effec- tive rates of expenditures on general services were highest followed in second and third places by expenditures on eco- nomic and educational services. In 1963 the average effec- tive rate for public debt services was higher than that of health and welfare services, but in 1969 the situation was re- versed. Among budgetary allocations for general services, de- fense always generated the highest average rate of benefits to households. General public administration, primary educa- tion, and transportation and communication were among the ma- jor expenditure sub-categories that generated high average effective expenditure rates. Effective rates of expenditures 210 Table 4.9--Generalized Expenditure Incidence Functions KEffective Expenditure Rates) = a + b (Annual Average Money Income)a] Intercept SIOpe R2 (1) On Money Income Base 1963 37.0 -.369 .9546 1969 54.9 -.935 .8982 (2) On Adjusted Income Base 1963 13.7 -.026 .9983 1969 19.0 -.076 .9809 aAverage Annual Money Income is in Thousands of Baht 211 that were presumed to benefit poor households relatively more than the rich, such as agriculture and health and welfare ser- vices, even taken together, were quite small, accounting for only 4 percent of household money income in 1963 and 7 penxnu: in 1969. Obviously, the lower income brackets gained when the two types of expenditures increased in 1969 compared to 1963-- notably in agricultural and irrigation spending--but the in- crease was still quite small on the whole. A fairly high rise in benefit rates also came from spending on general services, namely, defense and public administration. Comparing the effective rate of each type of expendi- ture among income classes, the lowest bracket generally re- ceived relatively higher expenditure benefits than any other except on such items as higher education and debt payments. In these two expenditures, the top bracket was the greatest beneficiary. That the total effective expenditure rate for the lowest income group based on money income was very high must be noted carefully. The bulk of these benefits (about 50 percent) was generated by such expenditures as defense, law enforcement and public administration spending. It may be ar- gued that from the point of View of the poorest household these benefits might be ranked lower in utility than the same amount of benefits from such expenditures as agricultural, educational, health and welfare spending. However, this point is value-loaded and, as such, should be left to the judgment and evaluation of each individual. 212 The Effects of Expenditure Programs on the Distribution of Income The previous section dealt with the usual way in which the income distributional effects of public expenditure pro- grams may be demonstrated by effective expenditure rates by income classes. This section discusses the effects of public expenditure programs upon the pattern of income distribution. In other words, the focus is directed to the change in the pattern of househOld income distribution after expenditure benefits are computed and assigned to each income class. Once the absolute amounts of estimated benefits are added to the income of each corresponding income bracket, a new distribu- tion should emerge. Table 4.10 shows these new distributions based on money and adjusted income concepts. Inspecting Table 4.10, one notes the small degree of income redistribution as a result of public expenditure pro- grams. On the money income base, the degree of redistribution is quite apparent, particularly in the lowest and highest brackets, but on the adjusted income base, the pre-fisc and the post-benefit income distributions are shown to be almost identical in 1963 and 1969. In other words, the expenditure programs of the Thai Government in 1963 and 1969, considered alone, effected very little change in the pre-fisc distribution of household income. This conclusion is supported by the change in the Gini concentration ratios. As shown in Table 4.11, within each individual year there is an improvement in income equality as indicated by the 213 o.ooa o.ooa o.ooa o.oon o.oo~ o.oo~ o.oon o.oon mmmmmao Haa m.~v m.m¢ v.om m.om o.om m.~m s.~m m.mm um>o_u:m ooo.wH m.m m.m m.o m.m mmm.sauooo.ma ~.HH m.HH i m.~a I H.ma A ~.s H.s » o.w H.m maa.¢~-¢oo.~a 9m 9m ma 3.. mmmfiuoooa o.s~ o.v~ I m.m~ _H «.mm A m.HH o.HH m.on m.oa I amm.m -ooo.o m.HH m.HH m.vH m.¢H o.on m.m H.¢H o.¢a amm.m -ooo.m m.m o.m a.m~ m.mH ~.m k.m m.va o.m~ ooo.m “was: udwfimbmom 08E unusambmom omEbE uflmcmmbmofiomflufim £088.38 03me mean mama moms moms Insane mmmmMHU . 9:85 aflfiflfiflo 283 Bums DE GOUBHHEAQ 9805 >982 $3 can mom.” .mmmmmfiu 0.505” an 9605 @3ng can mwcflz ufimmcmmuumom new omwmnmum mo cQwubnfi—umflo mmmusmoummlloaé manna 214 mm.mu mmmv. mmmv. mmmm mm.m+ I mm.m+ A . mm.ou mmmv. mmmm. momm $8 9505 839.9% 5 .m . mm.m- mmmm. ommm. momm mm.mu i mm.mn A mm.mu momm. mmmm. mmmm mmmm_maao:H mucazjco .m coflsflfiflo 838:5 ad .89 Smusflfimd cogs—Emma 9605 93H m5 5:33 «BUSH 90ch ummmmamaumom ommmumum 858088 uflmfimuumom omEbum 83 can mama 503qu ”Emmomumwoo go 5 at 38905 no TV mmmmuooo mmflfioumm H50 cum TI mmmwuocH no TV mmmouooo magnum mucwwowmmmoo H50 HMO? mmmm new mmmm .mummmsmmcm mEoocH cum 80298 mmficwamm new moflmm Signoocoo H50 ummmcwmlumom paw Damaging . v 0309 215 reduction in Gini concentration ratios from the pre-fisc in- come distribution to the post—benefit income distribution. In 1963 there was an improvement of 5.7 percent in income equality (or a 5.7 percent reduction in income inequality) when the post-benefit income distribution was compared to the pre-fisc income distribution based on household money income. The com- parable improvement in 1969 was 7.2 percent. As expected, the percentage improvement is greater with distribution based on money than on adjusted income. Although when each indivie dual year is viewed, the 1969 expenditure programs are shown to have more income redistributive power than the 1963 pro- grams. The effect is not sufficiently powerful or redistribu- tive to offset the extraneous factors that caused the deterio- ration of the adjusted income distribution from 1963 to 1969. This is evidenced by the fact that the 1969 post-benefit in- come distribution was about 4.6 percent more unequal than the 1963 post-benefit income distribution. As this is still smaller than 5.8 percent, which is the rate by which the pre-fisc in- come distribution had worsened from 1963 to 1969, one could conclude that, on an adjusted income base, government expendi- tures reduced income inequality by 1.2 percentage points from 1963 to 1969, which is not a large amount. Summary and Conclusion The statistical estimation of public expenditure bene- fits or expenditure incidence--the subject of this chapter-- is the obverse side of a fiscal incidence study, the reverse 216 being the tax incidence estimate. The chapter began with a discussion of the framework in which the study is to be car- ried out: the definition of a benefit, the identification of beneficiaries, and the selection of proper beneficiaries. Also discussed were various theoretical difficulties associ- ated with the quantification and allocation of the benefits of specific expenditures when beneficiaries are identifiable, as well as expenditures on such public goods as national de- fense, public health and law enforcement. In general, the conventional total benefits equal to- tal costs approach, or the approach which equates benefits to "costs incurred on behalf of" expected beneficiaries, has been adopted in this study. It offers the most consistent and practical way of dealing with the empirical estimates of ex— penditure incidence. After the 1963 and 1969 expenditures were classified into functional categories,and each type or category was ex- plained as to its nature and the bases upon which the intended benefits could be allocated, all expenditures were systemati- cally distributed to households in different income brackets. It was noted that the five major groups of public expendi- tures in Thailand, classified according to their function, are: economic, educational, health and welfare, general and debt payments. Of these, general service expenditures, en- compassing defense and general public administration, are the largest.' To determine the absolute amounts of expenditure benefits by income classes, money income and adjusted income 217 bases were used as denominators to arrive at the effective expenditure rates by type of expenditures as well as by total expenditure. These calculations form the basic estimates of expenditure incidence. Expenditure incidence in Thailand in 1963 and 1969 ranged between slightly regressive to mainly proportional de- pending upon the income bases used. When money income is used as a base, the incidence pattern is generally regressive be- cause the distribution of money income had a much wider dis- parity than the distribution of adjusted income. When adjusted income is used as the base, the incidence pattern becomes practically proportional. The lowest income bracket usually received the highest benefits per income than all other in- come brackets except for such expenditures as higher education and debt payments. Agricultural, primary education, and health and welfare expenditures proved to be the major items benefiting the lower income households relatively more than the upper income house- holds. The fact that transportation expenditures benefited the lowest and the highest income classes relatively more than others may be because the lowest group, in the farming sector, gained through easier access to markets to sell their produce, and the highest group benefited through shorter travel time for business and pleasure. Other expenditures were small and tended to benefit all income classes equally. 218 The change in the pattern of income distribution after government expenditures were allocated was quite small on the money income base and even more so on the adjusted income base. The computed rates of improvement in income equality due to government expenditures range from only 1.5 to 3.0 percent, depending upon which income concept is used. A general conclusion which could be drawn from this chapter is that public expenditures in Thailand as represented by the 1963 and 1969 budgets have done very little to redis- tribute income between rich and poor households. The im- provement in income equality as a result of these expenditure programs in the situation where they could be most redistribu- tive (that is, when money income is used as a base) was less than 8 percent in 1969 and 6 percent in 1963. Otherwise, the effects of government expenditures left Thai households in very much the same condition as before the inception of the programs. Although it is true that the 1969 expenditure programs were more income redistributive than those in 1963, it is doubtful that this can be taken as an indication of the gov- ernment's intention or deSire to redistribute income or re- duce income inequality through expenditure policies. In 1969 there was a noteworthy increase in relative benefits going to lower groups at the expense of higher income groups through expenditures in such areas as agriculture, primary education, transportation and health, but such increases were relatively 219 small on the whole. In all, the role of the government between 1963 and 1969 as an income redistributor through its expenditure poli- cies was rather limited. If the lower income brackets are to benefit more from government services, emphasis should be placed more on funding programs more attuned to their needs, such as various agricultural services, basic educational facilities, improved health and welfare services, and so on, than on such general services as defense, law enforcement and public administration. FOOTNOTES 1John H. Adler was the first to use this categoriza- tion of approaches. See his study, "The Fiscal System, the Distribution of Income and Public Welfarefl in Fiscal Policies and the American Economy,ed. Kenyon E. Poole, (New York: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1951), pp. 359—421.‘ 21bid., p.362. 3See Charles E. McLure, Jr., "On the Theory and Methodology of Estimating Benefit and Expenditure Incidence," paper presented at the Workshop on Income Distribution and its Role in Development, Programs of Development Studies, Rice University, April 26, 1974, (mimeographed). McLure distinguishes between the "expenditure incidence" and the "benefit incidence" with the former conforming to the study in the change in the distribution of income resulting from changes in relative product and factor prices, and the latter the change in household or individual income position after receiving real and imputed benefits from public expenditures. Since McLure's expenditure incidence study exists only in theory, the special meaning given to expenditure incidence which normally is interpreted as benefit incidence only serves to confuse the matter, at least in the context of the present study. Therefore, no such special meaning is followed here, and expenditure incidence and benefit incidence are still re- garded as synonymous. 4W. Irwin Gillespie, "Effect of Public Expenditure on the Distribution of Income" in Essays in Fiscal Federalism ed. Richard A. Musgrave, (Washington, D. C., The Brookings Institution, 1965), pp. 122-186. (Gillespie's U. 8. Study from now on); Idem., The Incidence of Taxes and Public Ex- penditures in the Canadian Economy (Ottawa: Queen's Printer, 1966). (Gillespie's Canadian Study from now on); Gian S. Sahota, "Public Expenditures and Income Distribution in Panama," United States Agency for International Development (USAID), Panama City, August, 1972, (mimeographed). 5 These points were made by McLure, pp. 49-59. 6Referring to the famous Impossibility Theorem by Kenneth J. Arrow. See his Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd ed. (New York: Wiley, 1963). 7See the two oft-quoted papers by Paul A. Samuelson "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure," Review of Economics and Statistics, 36 (November, 1954), 387-89, and "Diagrammatic 220 221 Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure," Review of Economics and Statistics, 37 (November, 1955), 350-56. 8Kenneth V. Greene, "Collective Decision—Making Models and the Measurement of Benefits in Fiscal Incidence Studies," National Tax Journal, 26 (June, 1973), p. 184. 9See Luc De Wulf, "Fiscal Incidence Studies in Develop- ing Countries: Survey and Critique," IMF Staff Papers, 22 (March, 1975). PP. 61-131. 101bid., p. 108. 11Development Economics Department, Public and Private Finance Division, World Bank. "Distributive Impact of Public Expenditures: A Research Proposal," September, 1973 (mimeographedL 12To put it more obtusely, a researcher in expenditure incidence study should not feel uneasy about using the word "beneficiaries" particularly when another, more detached word is to be used which in fact has the same meaning. l3See Gillespie's U. S. Study, pp. 140—5. l4See Henry Aaron and Martin McGuire, "Public Goods and Income Distribution," Econometrica, 38 (November, 1970), pp. 907-20; Shlomo Maital, "Public Goods and Income Distribution: Some Further Results" Econometrica, 41 (May, 1973), pp. 561- 68. The benefit allocation criteria used by Aaron, McGuire and Maital are quite unique but somehow their principal use in this study is rather inappropriate. See Appendix H in this study for the fiscal incidence result in Thailand based on Aaron-McGuire-Maital methods and the reasons why they are not used in the main study. 15Admittedly, the general methodology chosen here does not differ a great deal from what has been adopted in most other expenditure incidence studies. Nevertheless, this present study is an intertemporal study where the changes in the pat- terns of income distribution as a result of government expendi- tures between two reference years are compared. On the belief that the conceptual difficulties inherent in an incidence study are much reduced with an intertemporal investigating method, this is an important improvement over the conventional one- period benefit incidence study where the original or "pre-fisc" and "post-benefit" income distributions within a single period are compared. 16See, for example, Otto Eckstein, Water Resource Develop- ment (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1958). John V. Krutilla and Otto Eckstein, Multiple Purpose River Develop- ment (Baltimore: Resources for the Future, Inc., 1954). 222 17Thailand, Royal Irrigation Department "Feasibility Report on Lam Ta Kong Storage Dam Project, Korat Province," Vol. 1: Project Evaluation, Bangkok, April, 1963 (mimeo- graphed): Idem., "Report on Kang Krachan Project," Bangkok, February, 1961 (mimeographed). 18Ammar Siamwala, "Rice," Thammasat Universitprournal 3 (May, 1974), p. 22. Leslie E. Small, however, argues that at least the irrigation expenditures in the Central Plain areas produced the positive internal rate of return on the investment in the order of 6 to 9 percent. The problem of lack of farmers' initiative in response to the opportunities presented by the system (such as their non—production in dry season despite the availability of water) is still recognized and regarded as real and serious, and deserves special atten- tion. See Leslie E. Small, "Water Control and Development in the Central Plain of Thailand," Southeast Asia, (Spring, 1974), pp. 679-697. 19The idea that the allocation rules be so establish- ed originated from the studies on marketing channels of vari- ous agricultural products in the Central and Northeastern parts of Thailand. From these studies, it was known how a certain agricultural product passed through from a farmer to a middleman to a transport operator and so on until it reach- ed the final consumer within each farming season. The per- centage share of the profit margin to each of these agents would be a good indicator of how benefits from increased yields as a result of irrigation spending should be allocated. The 70-30 breakdown seems to be an appropriate criterion after various studies have been consulted. See Siamwala, pp. 65-74 for a summary of such marketing channel studies. 20The Department of Civil Aviation operates all air- ports in Thailand including Bangkok International Airport. Since only the really well-to-do travel by plane domestically and internationally, it is logical to assume that only the top income group benefits from this type of public expendi- ture. 21This 53/47 breakdown was obtained from Thailand, National Statistical Office, Statistical Yearbook of Thailand, No. 29, p. 281. 22See Gillespie's U. S. Study, pp. 140-45; see also Gillespie's Canadian study, pp. 97-105. 23Information obtained from the Department of Land Transport and the Police Department. 24See Gillespie's U. S. Study, pp. 146-147 and Gillespie's Canadian Study, pp. 105-110. 223 25Thailand, Ministry of Education, Education in Thailand: 1963 (Bangkok, no date). 26Thailand, National Statistical Office, Quarterly Bulletin of Statistics, 20 (March, 1972), p. 17. 27Thailand, National Educational Council, Private Expenditures of University Students, 1968-1969, (Bangkok, 1973). 28A rather odd, not so important but quite interesting example is seen in the part of defense appropriation which was spent on building and operating some golf courses in Thailand or the creation of a governmental administrative body supervising the operation of security market. Only higher income groups could benefit from such "general" ex- penditures. 29See Jacob Meerman, "Fiscal Incidence in Empirical Studies of Income Distribution in Poor Countries," AID Dis- cussion Paper No. 25, December, 1972 (mimeographedh p. 6. Perhaps a good test regarding the benefits of a defense sys- tem is to see who is most affected when such defense system collapses. It would be interesting to know the income dis- tribution of those individuals or families who managed to flee a country after its defense system collapsed under ex- ternal attack such as in South Vietnam or Cambodia in 1975. If most of these refugees were in higher income brackets, then the assumption adOpted here is not entirely false. 30Arnold C. Harberger, "Fiscal Policy and Income Dis- tribution," paper prepared for the Workshop on Income Dis- tribution in Less Developed Countries," Princeton University, June 12-13, 1974, p. 11. 31In the actual estimation, small principal payments were also included in these interest payments; the same analysis is assumed to apply for both these payments. 32See Gillespie's U. S. Study, pp. 157-158 and Gillespie's Canadian Study, pp. 128-137. 33McLure, p. 47. 34Ibid. 35Among them Gillespie; Sahota; Richard A. Musgrave and Peggy B. Musgrave, Public Finance in Theory and Practice (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1973), Edita Tan, "Taxation, Govern- ment Spending, and Income Distribution in the Philippines," paper presented for the Joint JERC-CAM Seminar on income 224 distribution, employment, and economic develOpment in South- east and East Asia, Tokyo, December 16-20, 1974. 36Thailand, Bank of Thailand, Monthly Bulletin. 12 (June, 1973): p. 36. CHAPTER V THE NET FISCAL INCIDENCE Unlike the previous two chapters, this one involves no major theoretical difficulty; it deals with the straight- forward subtraction of the tax incidence of Chapter 3 from the expenditure incidence of Chapter 4 to arrive at the net fiscal incidence of the government tax and expenditure ac- tivities. More specifically, this chapter will account for the income distributional effects of government taxes and ex- penditures in two customary ways. First, the effective ex- penditure rate of each income bracket will be subtracted by the effective tax rate of the same corresponding income class. The result may be called the effective fiscal rate or the net fiscal incidence of the Thai fiscal system. Second, the net effect of expenditure benefits minus tax burdens of each in- come class will be added to the "pre-fisc" or the original before-tax and before-benefit income distribution to see whether or to what extent the "post-fisc" or the after-tax and after-benefit income distribution changes. Alterations in the Gini concentration ratios associated with changes in income distributions also will be estimated. 225 226 Effective Fiscal Rates or Net Fiscal Incidence by Income Classes As the estimates of tax and expenditure incidence in Chapters 3 and 4 were carried out on the same five income brackets in 1963, and seven income brackets in 1969, the ab— solute fiscal incidence and the effective fiscal rates for those years can be obtained simply by subtracting the tax burden (effective tax rate) pertaining to each particular in- come bracket from its expenditure benefit (effective expendi- ture rate). For example, the absolute net fiscal incidence of the lowest income bracket (under Baht 3,000) in 1963 would be Baht 2,229.7 million minus Baht 1,911.0 million, or Baht 318.7 million. Table 5.1 shows the absolute net fiscal incidence by income classes in 1963 and 1969. The effective fiscal rates can be estimated by dividing these absolute incidence figures by the relevant money and adjusted income levels. The result- ing effective fiscal rates by income classes are shown in Table 5.2. Essentially, an effective fiscal rate shows the rela- tive net benefit (or net loss if the effective fiscal rate has a negative sign) which the households in different income brackets have received from the tax and expenditure policies of the government as a percentage of their money or adjusted income. The use of income as a weight is important in this incidence study because these rates across income classes could reveal whether the fiscal structure is regressive (pro-poor), 227 Table 5.1—-Absolute Net Fiscal Incidence, 1963 and 1969 (Amountsin.Millions of Baht) Income Classes (Baht 1963 1969 Under 3,000 '318.7 941.5 3,000- 5,999 138.5 697.2 6,000- 8,999 452.2 } 402.7 9,000-11,999 375.1 12,000-14,999 190.8 } 67.1 15,000-17,999 163.7 18,000 and over 694.1 1,010.8 All Classes 1,621.2 3,831.3 Source: Tables 3.2, 3.3, 4.3 and 4.4. 228 Table 5.2-~Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Money and a Adjusted Income, 1963 and 1969: Assumption I Based on Based on Income Classes Money Income Adjusted Income (Baht) 1963 1969 1963 1969 Under 3,000 7.1 38.9 2.1 10.7 3,000- 5,999 2.8 11.6 1.2 4.0 6,000- 8,999 6.6 2.7 }4.4 } 2.1 9,000-11,999 6.3 2.9 12,000-14,999 3.7 1.8 }1.5 } 0.7 15,000-17,999 3.7 1.9 18,000 and over 6.0 3.0 2.9 1.4 All Classes I 4.7 5.9 2.1 2.6 aThese are effective fiscal rates under Assumption I where the budget deficit is assumed to add directly to the income of households without reduction in real income through possible price increase. 229 progressive (pro-rich), or proportional. In general, a regres- sive fiscal system would generate relatively greater net bene- fits to lower than to higher income classes, so that the ef— fective fiscal rates will fall as the level of income rises. The opposite is true with a progressive fiscal system. A proportional or neutral fiscal system would be indicated by a constant effective fiscal rate across income brackets. Before proceeding to discuss the effective fiscal rates illustrated in Table 5.2, the reader should be informed about one important point about these rates. Both the 1963 and 1969 budgets were unbalanced: The expenditures to resi- dents exceeded the tax receipts from residents by Baht 1,621.2 million in 1963, and by Baht 3,831.0 million in 1969. These deficits are assumed to raise or add to the income of house- holds without any reduction in the income of the same house- holds either through taxes or through price increase. Table 5.2 was calculated on the assumption that the budget deficit has a "zero repercussive effect" upon any price adjustments that might occur due to the existence of such a deficit. In other words, the deficit merely adds more income to house- holds without them having to sacrifice or suffer in any other way.1 Hereafter this assumption will be referred to as As- sumption I. With the preceding qualification in mind, Table 5.2 may be examined. Three points are apparent: 230 (1) The average effective fiscal rates for all in- come classes for 1963 and 1969 were 4.7 and 5.9, respectively, under the money income base, and 2.1 and 2.6, respectively, under an adjusted income base. (2) All effective rates are positive across all in- come classes, meaning that, under Assumption I, all income classes gained absolutely from government fiscal activities. (3) The overall net incidence pattern in 1969 could be described as moderately regressive (pro-poor) under the money income base to slightly regressive under the adjusted income base. In 1963 no clear incidence pattern is discerni- ble. As the effective fiscal rates fluctuate slightly through- out the income range, the net fiscal incidence pattern could appropriately be termed a wandering proportional one. It is noted, however, that the effective fiscal rates for the top income class are higher than the average fiscal rates for all income classes. This indicates that, indeed, the effects of tax and expenditure policies was to redistribute income from some lower income brackets to this top income bracket, cer- tainly a redistribution in the wrong direction if one hypoth- esizes that a more egalitarian distribution is desirable. The pattern of net fiscal incidence perhaps may be seen more easily in the graphical presentation in Figures 5.1 and 5.2. In these figures the effective fiscal rates are plotted along the vertical axis and the average money income of households along the horizontal axis. 231 mood can mood .uumuuao usoocH mp .oaoonH mono: no woman now-m agenda o>uuoommuru«.m ousmmh 35m mo uccaaozs avocado onoocH "' ‘ ' ‘Il ‘ '- ‘I" | I," 1“ l‘-.. ‘ "Q'I‘E “' 'I‘ moms moms .......... can On on é Annuouomv omega Hannah o>uuoomum 232 mom“ was mwmd .mommnau oaoonH hp .osoosH vouusnv< no woman «ovum Hannah o>daoommmnnm.m ouawnk Scam mo 33.323 mouuuao osoocH A ( J 1 J moms moms .......... o“: om t Avcuouomv nuaam Hannah o>uvoomma I..IIIIIII II I11 233 From Figures 5.1 and 5.2 it is clear that the 1969 fiscal sys- tems were more regressive than those in 1963 both in the level and the pattern of net incidence. Under a money income base, the 1963 net fiscal incidence has a somewhat U-shaped pat- tern, although a very shallow one, whereas the 1969 net fis- cal incidence has a monotonically downward sloping pattern throughout. Under an adjusted income base, the net fiscal incidence patterns were practically prOportional in both years, with the situation in 1969 being slightly more favorable to the lowest two income classes. Following the practice adopted in the tax and expendi— ture analysis, it is possible to generalize about the net fis- cal incidence pattern in the same way as the tax and expendi- ture incidence patterns, that is, by regressing the effective fiscal rates upon the average household money income using the ordinary least-squares method. The functional form for the net fiscal incidence pattern, however, differs slightly from the original functional form for the tax and expenditure in- cidence patterns. Instead of expressing effective fiscal rates as a function of the annual average money income of households, the new functional form expresses effective fiscal rates as a function of the logarithms of the annual average money income of households. The main reason for the change is because the new functional form gives a much better good- ness of fit than the original form.2 The results of the generalized regression functions of net fiscal incidence are shown in Table 5.3, and these 234 Table 5.3—-Genera1ized Net Fiscal Incidence Functions: Assumption I KEffective Fiscal Rate) = a + b log (Average Annual Money Income)a] Intercept Slope R2 (1) On Money Income Base 1963 8.14 -l.044 .8085 1969 109.51 -25.066 .8420 (2) On Adjusted Income Base 1963 0.08 +0.40? .8388 1969 29.19 -6.472 .9014 aAverage Annual Money Income in Thousands of Baht 235 give general support to the results in Table 5.2 and Figures 5.1 and 5.2. The net fiscal incidence pattern in 1963 was barely regressive under the money income base and actually turned progressive under the adjusted income base, the same pattern in 1969 was clearly regressive throughout under both income bases. Comparing fiscal activities in 1963 and those in 1969, the latter were definitely more income equalizing than the former. The more exact extent to which the two fis- cal programs helped change the equality in the distribution of income will be discussed in the next section. The Effects of Fiscal Activities on the Distribution of Income Of paramount concern in a fiscal incidence study is the following question: What is the impact of government fiscal activities upon the distribution of income of house- holds? The effective fiscal rates discussed earlier showed mainly the level of fiscal incidence or net benefits weighted by two income concepts, and the general pattern of progres- sivity or regressivity of the fiscal programs. This section will examine the effects of such fiscal programs from an- other aspect, that is, the relative income position of each income class after net benefits from the government sector were added to the original, pre-fisc income levels. Table 5.4 presents the distribution of post-fisc money and adjusted income of households in 1963 and 1969. Let us first consider the money income portion of that table. Re- gardless how one views it, the degree of change in the pattern 236 o.oom o.oom o.oom o.oom o.oom o.oom o.oom o.oom mpmmmmo mam m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm . m.mm m.mm pm>o_pcm coo.mm m.m m.m m.m m.m .mmm.mm.ooo.mm m.mm i m.mH l m.mm i m.mm i m.m m.m . m.m m.m mmm.mmnooo.mm m.m m.m m.m m.m mmm.mmuooo.m m.mm I m.mm .1 m.mm i m.mm i m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm . mmm.m -ooo.m m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm m.m m.m m.mm m.mm mmm.m -ooo.m m.m m.m m.mm m.mm m.m m.m m.mm m.mm moo.m puns: ommmcumom ommmlmum ommmlumom ommmlwum ommmuumom ommmnmum ommmlumom ommmlmum mmmm mmmm mmmm lusmmv pogflbmd .8805 8...ng comm—53.339 mcduaH 5:9.“ 8330 9.85 H coin—Ema momma cam mood .mmmmmfiu 9505 an 9505 8pm: mg 98 moan: ommmluwom paw omfimlmum mo 2033.“ng mmfifioummllv .m magma. 237 of income distribution from the pre-fisc to the post-fisc situation can only be described as insubstantial. In 1963 the lowest income bracket gained less than one-half of a percentage point in its relative income position, whereas the positions of the middle three brackets slightly worsened, and the top income group gained by about 0.5 percentage points. In 1969, the degree of change was more distinct, yet still small. Of seven income brackets, the first four appear to be gainers and the last three losers, with the low- est income group gaining the highest and the top income group losing the most. When adjusted income is used as the base, the redis— tributional results become even smaller. The pre-fisc and the post-fisc income distributions in both 1963 and 1969 look almost identical, attesting to the fact that the fiscal activities of the government had very small ifiCome redistribu- tional effects indeed upon Thai households. That there was more income redistribution in 1967 than in 1963 is obvious from Table 5.4. Still, it would be interesting to see ex- actly how much the fiscal policies of each year affected the inequality of income as measured by Gini concentration ratios. Table 5.5 presents the estimates of Gini concentra- tion ratios before and after government fiscal activities took effect, and the percentage changes in these ratios both between the pre-fisc and the post-fisc situations of a single year and between the post-fisc situations of 1963 and 1969. 238 ao.mu mama. mmmv. mama av.m+ a mm.m+ a ma.o+ aame. . mama. mama mmmm msoocm pmumsmpa co Ame om.vu mama. ommm. mama mm.m| a mm.a| a Na.ou aaam. mmaa. mama mmmm mEooca mmcoz so may mam”. mam”. 8:: am”. am”. mcu canvas umamnumom omamlmum ucmaommmmou omamuumom omamuwum . . uwmw mama new mama cmm3umm ucmaoammmoo acau ca A+V mmmmuocH no Ala mmmmuomo wmwucmoumm acau ca A+v wmmmuoca Ho Ala mammuomo womucmoumm mucmaoamwmoo acaw a ceaumfismmd ”mama mam mama .muaamsvmca OEOOCH Ca mmmcmco momucmoumw Ucm moaumm Geaumuucmocou acao omamlumom can omamumumlum.m magma 239 On a money income base, the 1963 post—fisc income distribution improved from .5627, the pre-fisc Gini ratio, to .5581, re- ducing the inequality area by 0.8 percent. The similar change for 1969 was from .5550 to .5289, or a rate of improvement in income equality of 4.7 percent. Comparing the post-fisc dis- tributions based on money income in both years, the effect of the 1969 fiscal policies accounted for a reduction of al— most 4 percentage points in the inequality index from 1963. Such an effect is much reduced when adjusted income is used as a base. The pre-fisc Gini ratios were .4559 and .4822, respectively, for 1963 and 1969. As a result of taxes and expenditures, they changed to .4566 and .4725, indicating a very slight worsening in income equality in 1963 and a slight improvement of the same in 1969. Nevertheless, the overall effect in comparing the 1963 to the 1969 post-fisc adjusted income distribution is seen to be a general worsen- ing in the degree of income equality by about 3.5 percent. This certainly does not mean that fiscal activities in 1969 made households worse off than fiscal activities in 1963. On the contrary, 1969 policies did redistribute income from higher to lower income classes, thus improving the Gini:ratios of income inequality. However, as the pre-fisc income dis- tribution based on the adjusted income concept became more unequal in 1969 compared to 1963, the tax and expenditure policies in 1969, which were only slightly regressive to pro- portional, were not strong or redistributive enough to off- set the deterioration in income equality due to governmental 240 and other undetermined external influences. Since the 1969 pre-fisc distribution shows an approxi- mate 5.8 percent deterioration in income equality from 1963 on the distribution of income based on adjusted income, and since the increase in the Gini ratio in the 1969 post-fisc income distribution was only 3.5 percent, then roughly 2.3 percentage points should be regarded as the extent to which 1969 fiscal policies reduced income inequality from 1963 based on adjusted income. Similarly, on a money income base, the post-fisc distribution in 1969 was 5.2 percent more equal than the similar distribution in 1963. Compared to 1.4 per- cent which is the extent to which the 1969 pre-fisc distribu- tion was more equal than the 1963 pre-fisc distribution, it could be said that the 1969 fiscal activities had about 3.8 percentage point (that is, 5.2 percent minus 1.4 percent) more income equalizing power than the 1963 fiscal activities. These two figures (3.8 percentage points and 2.3 percentage points) should indeed be identical; the small divergency is probably due to errors in statistical estimation. It could be concluded, therefore, that between 1963 and 1969 the government, through its taxes and expenditures, effected between a 2.3 and 3.8 percentage point reduction in income inequality as measured by-Gini coefficients, a feat which could easily have been accomplished by imposing only a 2.5 percent extra tax on the income of the highest income group in 1969 and transferring this amount of tax revenue to the lowest income households.5 Also, the reader is reminded 241 that the 2.3 to 3.8 percentage point reduction mentioned above is true only under Assumption I, where the budget defi- cit is assumed to have no detrimental effect through price adjustments but to add directly to the income of households. Had this assumption been proven untenable or false, the pat- tern of post-fisc income distribution could have changed, and this, of course, could have resulted in a greater in- equality index. It is possible, as will be shown later, that depending on alternative assumptions about the income distri- butional effects of a budget deficit, the government could indeed worsen, not improve, the income equality of households through its fiscal activities. Budget Deficit in Fiscal Incidence Studies The significance of the existence of a deficit in the public sector is generally recognized in almost all fiscal in- cidence studies. Gillespie devoted a substantial part of his Canadian study to a discussion of how the problems should be dealt with in an empirical investigation.3 Similar efforts also have been made by J. A. Johnson and G. S. Sahota.4 The results, however, have been less than gratifying, for there is still no single most satisfactory way of dealing with the empirical estimation of the possible distributional impact of the budget deficit and its financing. A budget deficit is said to exist when the govern- ment's expenditures exceed its revenues in any fiscal year. There are several avenues Open for the government to finance 242 such a deficit. It may print more money, use up past reserves, borrow from domestic as well as foreign sources, or receive financial help from overseas. Normally, the government will use a combination of these methods. What is most pertinent here is the government policy of increasing the money supply, since this will normally raise the price level in most econo- mies unless they are characterized by high unemployment or underutilization of resources. The increase in the price level could either partially reduce the income generating power of the deficit (that is, through the income multiplier), or eliminate it completely depending upon other factors. The problem is further complicated by the fact that even if the overall extent of the price increase is known, it is still difficult to know how different income brackets are differently affected by such an increase. Various studies have been directed to answering the question of who would be affected by price increases, and by how much, but the results obtained so far are not conclusive. Generally, however, it is believed that lower income groups suffer more under infla- tion compared to higher income groups, for several reasons: A higher proportion of the income of the poor is spent on necessary consumption, such as food and clothing, which usu- ally is subject to price increases more than other items, or the earnings of the poor do not increase as fast as the price level, or other factors.6 Also, if the traditional view is correct that inflation harms wage-earners and other fixed- income groups but benefits property owners and business firms, 243 then this would imply that the lower brackets will suffer more than the upper brackets since wage and salary earners generally tend to be bunched in the lower to middle income groups, and the business operators and property owners in the higher income groups. But the foregoing discusses only one dimension of the problem; many other questions regarding a budget deficit could be considered, among them: What if deficit financing causes not only a price increase but also unemployment? How does one isolate the portion of the deficit that affects only nonresidents? How does one account for the distributional effects of the deficit financed by foreign assistance? These problems cannot be solved unless certain assumptions are made as to how the government's deficit should be treated. Most fiscal incidence studies seem to ignore the income distribu- tional effects of the public deficit and assume that it only adds to existing income, just as it has been treated thus far in this study. -A few alternative assumptions designed to "eliminate" the deficit also have been used, resulting mainly in the change in the level of net incidence but not its pat- tern. In Thailand the "functional" budget deficit amounted to Baht 1,621.2 million in 1963 and Baht 3,831.9 million in 1969. By "functional" is meant the deficit which affects only the resident households considered in this study, not the actual accounting deficit, nor the total amount of public ‘244 borrowing to finance the deficit in that year. In other words, the functional deficit is derived simply from subtracting the total adjusted tax revenues from the total adjusted expendi- tures in each year. Three assumptions concerning the treatment of budget deficits are considered in the case of Thailand. Assumption I has already been discussed: The deficit is assumed to have a zero or no repercussive effect on price adjustments due to the existence of the deficit and its financing. This has been the standard assumption so far. According to Assumption II, the price effect is assumed to cancel out completely the in- come generating effect of the deficit. The deficit is then eliminated, and the budget is hypothetically balanced. How- ever, only the level of net benefit is changed, not its pat— tern. Assumption III is somewhat similar to Assumption II, that is, the price effect is assumed equal to the income ef— fect, but the distribution of the effect by income classes is assumed to be more burdensome to the lower than to the upper income classes. As the net fiscal incidence according to Assumption I has already been considered, only Assumption II (deficit with "neutral" repercussive effect) and Assumption III (deficit with "de-equalizing" repercussive effect) will be discussed below. When the deficit is eliminated and the effect on ex- isting income distribution is neutral (Assumption II), the change in the effective fiscal rates is simply a matter of subtracting the average net benefit rate for all income 245 classes from the effective fiscal rate derived under Assump- tion I of each income bracket. The new effective fiscal rates would not be all positive, meaning that the deficit finance benefited some and not others. However, post-fisc income distribution would remain the same, since the neutral effect touches only the level of effective fiscal rates, not the en- suing distribution of income. Under Assumption III, the deficit is said to cause a relatively heavier burden to the lower than to the upper in- come classes, due to price adjustments. As there is no basis upon which such a deficit could be deducted from each income class, it is arbitrarily assumed that each household is equal- ly affected by it. In other words, financing the deficit has the effect of a poll tax upon each head of household in Thai- land. Since most households are found in the lower spectrum of the income distribution scale, the elimination of a deficit in this way appears to "de-equalize" income equality. The results of the hypothetical elimination of a func- tional budget deficit using the above two assumptions are shown in Tables 5.6 and 5.7. Table 5.6 shows the effective fiscal rates under Assumption II and Table 5.7 shows the re- sulting percentage distribution of income under Assumption III. Although the pattern of effective fiscal rates in Table 5.6 is the same as that shown in Table 5.2, use of As- sumption II gives a clearer view of whether and in which direction the redistribution has occurred. In 1963, on both 246 Table 5.6--Effective Fiscal Rates Based on Money and Adjusted Income, 1963 and 1969: Assumption II Based on Based on Income Classes Money Income Adjusted Income (Baht) 1963 1969 1963 1969 Under 3,000 +2.4 +33.0 +0.1 +8.1 3,000- 5,999 -1.8 +5.7 -0.8 +1.4 6,000- 8,999 +0.6 +0.1 - -0.3 +0.1 9,000-11,999 +0.4 +0.3 12,000-14,999 -2.3 -0.8 -3.2 -1.3 15,000-17,999 -2.2 -0.7 18,000 and over +1.3 -2.9 +0.8 -l.2 All Classes - 0 0 0 0 Fli' III‘II Illl‘l 247 GOauafiaHumao 968a moan: n2 cognaaumao mEooca mung o.ooa odoa o.ooa mama odoa mama o.ooa 0.8a «dummao a2 a.mv a.am m.am m.mm m.ma m.ma . m.mm m.mm um>o_a:m oom.aa m.m m.m a.a a.a mmm.mauooo.aa m.aa a m.aa a m.ma a a.ma a a.m a.m m.m a.m mmm.aauooo.~a m.m m.m m.m m.m mmm.aanooo.m a.mm a o.am a a.am a a.a~ a m.aa a.aa a.oa a.oa mmm.a uooo.a m.aa m.aa ~.aa m.ma m.m m.m m.ma m.ma mmm.m uooo.m o.a o.a m.ma m.ma m.m m.m m.aa m.ma coo.m amass omamauumom 8315 Baabmom oma aumam omapuumom ammumam 8amau8m omamuoam 38am: mama mama mama mama mammmao mg aaa coaumasmma umama pan mama .mmmmmau 9:85 man .9593 pmumflnaad paw Name—oz omamlumom Em Omahnmam mo companahamao mmflsmoummllm .a magma. 248 money and adjusted income bases, the middle three income brackets seemed to be the net losers or redistributors of income to the top and bottom income brackets. In 1969, it was also clear that the top three income groups under both income bases were the net losers. Again, it must be mentioned that the extent of redistribution is quite small in both years. A new kind of picture emerges when the deficit is eliminated under Assumption III. As expected, the lower in- come classes now appear to be the heavy losers (in 1963) or small gainers (in 1969); in all cases, the top income class received positive gains. The net fiscal incidence pattern no longer could be called slightly regressive to proportional, as before, but rather proportional to slightly progressive. The above assertion is supported by the change in the post-fisc income distribution under Assumption III shown in Table 5.7. That the lower income classes are worse off and the upper income classes better off after the effects of gov- ernment fiscal activities than before is clearly evident in both years. In 1963, for example, the post-fisc income share of the lowest bracket fell from 13.0 percent to 11.8 percent under the money income base, and from 19.8 percent to 19.2 percent under the adjusted income base. In 1969, the income position of the lowest income class was actually improved by a very small percentage, but the positions of the three low- est brackets taken together deteriorated. Improvement in the top income group's position ranges from as low as 0.3 to as high as 1.7 percentage points. an an In su co: co. fr: ce] AS: lee thu 110‘ uni fi th 991 is 0n tr ha to Cr 249 The pre-fisc and post—fisc Gini concentration ratios and percentage changes in these ratios in, and between, 1963 and 1969 under Assumption III are presented in Table 5.8. In 1963, the post-fisc Gini concentration ratios under As- sumption III increased from .5627 to .5838 based on money in- come, and from .4559 to .4660 based on adjusted income. The corresponding increase in 1969 was from .5550 to .5614, and from .4822 to .4853. The percentage increase in income in- equality from the pre-fisc to the post-fisc situation is es- timated at between 2.2 to 3.8 percent in 1963 and between 0.6 to 1.2 percent in 1969, depending upon the income con- cepts used. This is a startling change from the results under Assumptions I and II because, under those assumptions, at least the post-fisc mgngy income distribution improved over the pre-fisc mgngy income distribution in both 1963 and 1969; now, under Assumption III, the post-fisc income distribution ‘ under both income bases becomes more unequal than the pre- fisc income distribution. In short, under Assumption III, the government aggravated instead of mitigated income in- equality in Thailand. The question then arises as to whether Assumption III is too extreme. It does not appear to be. In fact, in the only study on the effects of price increases upon income dis- tribution of households in Thailand, Dr. Oey Astra Meesook has commented that it is the lower income groups relative to the higher who are more adversely affected by general in- creases in the consumer price index. She reasons as follows: 250 aa.o+ mama. «mam. mama aa.m+ a. mm.a+ a mm.~+ oaam. mama. mama mmmm msooca pmumsaam co Ame aa.a+ aaaa. oaaa. mama ma.m- a mm.a- a mm.m+ amam. mmaa. mama mmmm mEoocH mono: co aav .umao .umao .umao .umaa mEooca mEooca woaawm wEoocH mEooca Omahlumom. omamlwum may canvas omamuumom omamumum unmaoamwmoo mama paw mama cmmzumm unmaoammmou acao ca a+v mammHUCH no any mmwmuomo mmmucmoumm acao ca a+v mmmmHOCH Ho Ala mmmmaomo momucwoamm mucmaoamwmoo acau and» aaa coaumeammd ”mama can mama .muaamsvmsa mEooca ca momcmnu mmmucwoamm 0cm moaumm coaumaucmocou acaw omamlumom 0cm omamlmamula.m manna ,_—‘. .n—‘L ” .— - _ fl -Q . u-I‘ “ w A“...- a ‘— ‘ dif inc« dif: per: eSti; mateE ernme Come these Sente( inCOm Pre-f 251 The poor suffer more first of all because total expenditures form a large percentage of their incomes so that there is less of an income margin, if any, to enable them to keep real consumption at a constant level. Moreover, when real consumption declines for the poor it is a serious problem if they are near or actually below subsistence level. Our calculations show that further aggrava- tion of the problem is brought on by the un- favorably larger overall price increase fac- ing the poor during recent years.7 Although Dr. Meesook has quantitatively compared the different distributional effects of price increases across income classes, such a scheme cannot be applied here due to differences in income class structures, income concepts, and periods under study. It is sufficient, nonetheless, to say that price increases due to deficit financing could have a de—equalizing effect upon the existing income distribution if it is assumed that each household equally bears the burden of such price increases, as Table 5.8 has shown. Summary and Conclusions This chapter has brought together the tax incidence estimation of Chapters 3 and the expenditure incidence esti- mates of Chapter 4, netting out the residual effects of gov- ernment taxes and expenditures upon the distribution of in- come of households in Thailand in 1963 and 1969 and between these two years. As in Chapters 3 and 4, the results are pre- sented in two ways, according to effective fiscal rates and income classes, and according to the changes in the original, pre-fisc income distribution after the net benefits have been ‘—‘ adde tior had est the est the both to t in 1 siVe 1963 mEdSI Dre-1 Undel tribL tribL equal 252 added and showing the related changes in the Gini concentra— tion ratios. Under a money income base, the net fiscal incidence had a U-shaped pattern in 1963 with the lowest and the high- est income groups enjoying the highest net benefits; in 1969 the pattern was monotonically downward sloping from the low- est to the top income group. Under an adjusted income base, the net fiscal incidence became more or less proportional in both 1963 and 1969, as expected. Because the net benefits to the lowest income classes were much larger in 1969 than in 1963, the 1969 fiscal programs were definitely more regres- sive or pro-poor than the 1963 programs. The post-fisc distribution of money income both in 1963 and 1969 showed an improvement in income equality as measured by Gini concentration ratios when compared to the pre-fisc money income distribution in the respective years. Under the adjusted income base, however, the post-fisc dis- tribution became slightly more unequal than the pre-fisc dis— tribution in 1963, while in 1969 the improvement in income equality was still evident in the post-fisc distribution. The foregoing conclusion is based on the assumption that the budget deficit which existed both in 1963 and 1969 only adds directly to the income'of households. If the budget deficit is assumed to raise the price level, and if each household is assumed to suffer the price increase equally, then it can be shown that the post-fisc income distribution in both 1963 and 1969 would be more unequal than the corresponding -”-—— __———-———‘———a pre- assu trib ture to h inco come gene tiOH. Of V, 253 pre-fisc income distribution. The purpose of this latter assumption is to demonstrate that the extent of income redis- tribution of the Thai government through its tax and expendi- ture policies is so small that, by changing the assumption as to how the budget deficit differentially would affect each income class, the government fiscal programs could become in- come de-equalizing instead of income equalizing. Although the year 1969 showed a promising trend toward greater income equality (or less income inequality) over the year 1963 as a result of government fiscal policies, apparently this trend was too weak and too slow to be meaningful. This was mainly because, on the tax side, too much revenue was col- lected from indirect taxes and too little from direct taxes, and, on the expenditure side, too much benefit to the lower income classes was derived from such general expenditures as defense, law enforcement and public administration. It may be questionable to assume that one Baht's benefit from these general expenditures has exactly the same value as one Baht's benefit from such specific or transfer expenditures as educa- tional spending and child allowances, at least from the point of View of the poorest section of the population. If the more urgent objective of the government is to help the poorest section of the population, it would be most desirable for fiscal policies to be reoriented toward fewer indirect taxes and general expenditures, and toward more di- rect taxes and more specific and transfer expenditures, es- pecially the categories which contribute most to the direct ar hc in si 1e‘ the dis Chi nua in . the cruc inco come State QIOWt 254 and indirect raising of the income positions of the poor households. One final note about the significance of income level in relation to income inequality should be mentioned. By simply looking at the considerable increase in the income level in 1969 compared to 1963, one could be led to believe that the growing economy was simultaneously easing the income distribution problem. The study by this researcher and Chintana Chernsiri pointed out that even when the average an- nual income of a family in the lowest income class was tripled in 1969 it was still not sufficient to raise that family above the poverty level as defined for that year.8 What is more crucial, of course, is the inequality in the distribution of income, a factor that easily could be overshadowed by the in- come rise. In conclusion, it seems appropriate to quote a cogent statement made by Oey Astra Meesook on the issue of income growth and income inequality: A major question...is whether it is in fact the case that rapid overall growth of income makes it easier to bring about changes in the way that income is distributed. The argument usually put forward is that a rapid rise in income makes it unnecessary to actually re- distribute income. By simply ensuring that a larger proportional increase accrues to the poor than to the rich, it is possible to im- prove the distribution of income in a way which is not disagreeable to the rich. Al- though this is a notion which is being bandied about a great deal, our analysis suggests that rapid growth of income may simply dull the pains of inequality: in a situation of high growth rates, it becomes less noticeable that there is still a great deal of inequality 255 around. People are that their position thus less likely to some.9 fooled into thinking has improved and are be politically trouble- FOOTNOTES 1The most obvious case where this is possible is when the government finances the deficit through some windfall revenues, through past savings, or through foreign grants in a less than fully employed economy. 2The other reason is that the original functional form when used on the 1963 money income data gives a general- ized net fiscal incidence curve with a positive slope, sig- nigying a progressive net fiscal incidence pattern. This contradicts the result of the change in the post-fisc money income distribution as measured by Gini concentration ratios (to be discussed later in the chapter) which showed that under money income base the post-fisc income distribution in 1963 was still more equal than the pre-fisc income distribution of the same year. After an experiment with two other func— tional forms-~the semi-log and the double-log--which showed the net fiscal incidence curve with a negative slope as ex- pected, it was decided to use the semi—log functional form which also yielded the best overall goodness of fit. There was no contradiction regarding the net fiscal incidence slope under adjusted income in 1963, however; the positive slope was not unexpected. 3W. Irwin Gillespie, The Incidence of Taxes and Public Expenditures in the Canadian Economy. (Ottawa: Queen's Printer, 1966), pp. 164-179. 4 James A. Johnson, The Incidence of Government Reve- nues and Expenditures (Ottawa: Queen's Printer, n.d.), pp. 73-6; Gian S. Sahota, "Public Expenditures and Income Dis- tribution in Panama," United States Agency for International Development, Panama City, August, 1972, (mimeographed). 5The experiment was carried out by deducting 2.5 per- cent from the total money income of the highest bracket and adding this to the income of the lowest bracket. The new Gini coefficient was then computed from this new distribution of income the result of which was a reduction of about 4 per- cent in income inequality compared to the original income distribution. 6Oswald Brownlee and Alfred Conrad, for example, claim Specifically that inflation not only hurts the lower income classes but also benefits the upper income classes. George L. Bach and Albert Ando, on the other hand, maintain that for 256 on Uni men Jou Fac 257 a moderate inflation the redistributional effects are likely to be small, and more or less neutral. On a general context of incurring a public debt, however, Hugh Dalton and Alvin Hansen, among others, believe that internal debt creates higher relative real burden upon the lower income classes and is thus likely to intensify inequality of wealth and in- come rather than to mitigate it. See Oswald H. Brownlee and Alfred Conrad, "Effects upon the Distribution of Income of a Tight Money Policy," American Economic Review, 51 (May, 1961), pp. 74-85; George L. Bach and Albert Ando, "The Redistribu- tional Effects of Inflation," Review of Economics and Sta- tistics, 39 (February, 1957), pp. 1-13; Hugh Dalton, Princi- ples of Public Finance (London, 1923), p. 192; Alvin H. Hansen, Fiscal Policy and Business Cycles (New York, 1941), p. 179. 7Oey Astra Meesook, "The Impact of Price Increases on Different Income Groups," Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, August, 1975, p. 11 (mimeographed). 8Medhi Krongkaew and Chintana Chernsiri, "The Measure- ment of the Poverty Level in Thailand," Thammasat University Journal, 5 (June-September, 1975) (in Thai). 9Meesook, Income Distribution in Thailand (Bangkok: Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, 1975), pp. 83-84. (II I t [lull I I I ‘ CHAPTER VI SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS, AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS Summaryof Purpose and Procedures The purpose of this study was to measure empirically the income redistributional impact of taxes and public ex- penditures in Thailand in, and between, 1963 and 1969. In the language of public finance this is known as a "fiscal incidence study.” Unlike the more conventional type, however, this study emphasized the intertemporal effects of fiscal ac- tivities upon income distribution. In other words, it was primarily interested in comparing the change in income dis- tribution as a result of fiscal activities in 1969 with 1963. To use more precise terminology, this research estimated and compared "post-fisc" income distribution in 1969 with "post- fisc" income distribution in 1963. Knowledge of the redis- tributional impact would be useful not only as a means of measuring the government's performance in terms of income distribution, but also as a policy guideline or as an indica- tion of the direction in which the government might move if it wished to make some concrete changes in the existing pat- tern of income distribution. The persistent and severe inequality of income in Thailand was one of the major factors prompting this study. 258 l I [Ii I I{ .II I .(I. .I I 259 Since it is undoubtedly the government, more than any other element in the economy, which is capable of changing the pat- tern of income distribution of individuals or households, the investigation of the government's role in the distribution of income as reflected through its tax and expenditure policies, was a reasonable beginning. Such information would be a logical first step toward an efficient economic policy aimed at reducing the present income inequality. Admittedly, the ideological bias of this study is toward greater income and economic equality within the present democratic form of government. The scope of the research was limited to the tax and expenditure impact on household income at the national level. Lack of data, time, and resources did not permit a more de- tailed investigation at the regional, provincial, or sectoral level. Nevertheless, the information gathered more than com- pensated for the above limitation. Within this framework, the study attempted to estimate income distribution in 1963 and 1969 as a basis for further estimation of tax and ex— penditure incidence. Special attention was given to estimating the income dis- tribution in 1963 and 1969 as accurately as possible. This was necessary because an incorrect or inaccurate income base could distort the true pattern of tax and expenditure inci- dence. The basic data for income distribution estimates for 1963 and 1969 were taken from the household expenditure survey of 1962—1963 and the socio-economic survey of 1968-1969 260 respectively. Both were conducted by the National Statistical Office of Thailand. However, the income distribution obtained was the distribution of money income, which is only part of real income. This latter is defined in the Simons-Haig tra- dition as consumption plus the change in net wealth. Many ad- justments were made to money income in an effort to obtain a more comprehensive income base. Among the income elements added to money income were adjustments for the underreporting of incOme in the surveys and for under-estimated imputed rents of owner-occupied homes, income in kind, net corporate savings, and indirect taxes. The new income concept, called "adjusted income," was used as an alternative income base to the money income concept. Once income bases were known, the burden of taxation by income classes was estimated. The procedures used did not differ substantially from other tax incidence_studies. First, it was assumed that the burden of taxation should be measured in terms of a reduction in real income of taxpaying households. Then the question of incidence shifting had to be answered: Who ultimately bears the burden of each tax? A large part of Chapter 3 was devoted to resolving this problem. When the incidence problems were resolved, each major tax and government revenue in Thailand was allocated to various households based on different allocation rules. These rules generally followed the patterns of household expendi- tures on certain groups of commodities and other distributive series, the information being available from the household 261 expenditure surveys. The incidence of the total tax programs falling on a particular income class was then obtained by sum— ming up the absolute burden of each tax pertaining to that income class. When these absolute burdens were expressed as percent- ages of income levels of each class, the result obtained was the effective tax rate by income class. Subtracting these amounts from the original or "pre-fisc" income distribution yielded the "post-tax" income distribution. To account for the distributional impact of the tax system by the simple sub- traction of the absolute tax burdens from original income levels requires an assumption that the original or pre—fisc income distribution was indeed what would have resulted if the present tax system had been replaced by a proportional income tax of equal yield. This is the so-called differential incidence approach. Thus, the pre-fisc and post-tax income distributions within the same year could be compared, as could post-tax income distributions of two different years-- in this case 1963 and 1969--for evidence of a change in in- .come distribution. In a similar fashion, the incidence of public ex- penditures was estimated by first assuming that public ex- penditures generate benefits that add to the real income of households. Conceptual difficulties inherent in the quantifi- cation of expenditure benefits, especially those from such social goods as national defense and public health, necessi- tated the adoption of the accounting approach to benefit 262 allocation, that is, the assumption that total benefits are equal to total costs. Thus, actual government spending is allocated to expected first-round beneficiaries, known as a "cost-incurred-on-behalf-of approach." Once this decision was made, public expenditures were classified into five func- tional categories, and consideration was given as to who the prospective beneficiaries were and how the benefits should be allocated. Then all benefits of each income class were summed and divided by corresponding income levels to arrive at the effective expenditure rates. These same benefits were added to the existing, or pre-fisc, income distribution to arrive at the new, post-benefit, income distribution. The reasoning underlying this procedure was that the patterns of the effective expenditure rates and the changes registered in the post-bene- fit income distribution should reveal the income redistribu- tional nature of government expenditure programs. Determining the net fiscal incidence, that is, the incidence of the entire fiscal program, was simply a matter of finding the net benefits (expenditure benefits minus tax burdens) of each income class and expressing them in relation to the income level of that income class. This process yield- ed the effective fiscal rates. When the net benefits were added to the existing income distribution, the new income dis- tribution obtained is the "post-fisc" distribution. This, of course, was the final result and the one of prime interest in this study. 263 Conclusions Since the main study is divided into three parts-- tax incidence, expenditure incidence, and net fiscal incidence—— the conclusions will be presented in the same way. Tax incidence The four conclusions concerning tax incidence are: First, under a money income base, the tax programs in Thailand in 1963 and 1969 were generally--almost monotomi- cally-regressive across income classes. The effective tax rates ranged from 20.8 to 42.7 percent, and from 25.7 to 47.0 percent, of household money income in 1963 and 1969, respec- tively. The pattern of tax regressiveness in these two years was practically identical. Second, under the adjusted income base, the regres- sivity was almost eliminated; the tax systems exhibited a generally proportional pattern of incidence. The use of the adjusted income base therefore provided the lower bound of the effects of the tax programs, with the money income base providing the upper bound. If this interpretation is accepted, then the degree of tax burden in Thailand in 1963 and 1969 ranged from regressive to proportional at best; it could in no way be considered progressive. Third, regarding specific taxes, only the personal income tax and taxes on property showed a progressive incidence pattern; the others showed either a clearly regressive pattern 264 (business taxes, selective sales taxes, and import duties), or a U-shaped pattern (government receipts from state monopo- lies). But very few taxes were progressive. Taxes on in- come and property combined constituted only about 8 percent of total government revenues in both 1963 and 1969. Fourth, it is obvious that when a tax is regressive, the after-tax income distribution will be made more unequal. This was true in Thailand in 1963 and 1969. The degree of income inequality in the after-tax income distribution as measured by Gini concentration ratios, increased from 1.0 to 8.4 percent in 1963, and from 0 to 5.3 percent in 1969, depend- ing upon the income concepts used. Although the Gini ratios revealed that the tax programs of 1969 were less income de- equalizing (or more income equalizing) than the 1963 programs, the reduction in the Gini coefficient was very small, amount- ing only to about one or two percentage points. Expenditure Incidence The four conclusions concerning expenditure incidence are: First, based on the money income concept, the expendi- ture programs of the Thai Government in 1963 and 1969 showed a generally regressive or pro-poor pattern from the lowest to the highest income brackets. In 1969 the incidence pattern was clearly and steadily downward sloping, whereas in 1963 it was also downward sloping, but it turned slightly upward at the top income bracket. This pattern is almost identical 265 to that of the tax programs considered earlier, the only major difference being that the expenditure incidence of the lowest income class was much higher than the tax incidence of the same income class. This indicates that the poorest households reaped relatively greater net real benefits from government fiscal activities, at least from a money income point of view. Second, when the adjusted income base was used, ex- penditure incidence flattened out considerably. The 1963 pattern, when show diagrammatically, became almost a straight line, while the 1969 pattern still showed a very high level of expenditure incidence in the lowest income class. But for the other classes, the incidence pattern was more or less proportional, with a slight increase in incidence in the middle portion of the household range. On the whole, except for the lowest income group in 1969, all income classes seem to have received benefits from public expenditures in amounts proportional to their adjusted income. Third, hardly any expenditure item was shown to be progressive or pro-rich, with the exception, perhaps, of in- terest payments on the public debt, which is assumed to bene- fit upper income bracket debt holders. The expenditures most beneficial to lower income groups included those for agricul- ture, primary education, and health and social welfare. The benefits from general service expenditures, including mainly defense, law enforcement, and public administration, were also very regressive. 266 Fourth, if expenditure benefits are assumed to add di- rectly to the income of households, the income distribution after expenditure benefits are allocated, or the "post-benefit" income distribution, must be more equal than the original, pre-fisc income distribution. In this study, the Gini concen- tration ratios for post-benefit income distribution in 1963 improved by about 0.7 to almost 5.7 percent over pre-fisc in- come distribution, depending upon the income concepts used. The corresponding rate of improvement in 1969 was between al- most 1.7 percent to over 7.2 percent. The 1969 expenditure programs were more income equalizing than the 1963 programs, although both could be criticized for insufficient expendi- tures in the areas benefiting the poor most directly, such as primary education in rural areas and health and social wel- fare benefits. For maximum redistribution, too much was spent in both years in the areas of dubious benefit to the poor, such as in defense and general bureaucracy. Net Fiscal Incidence Concerning net fiscal incidence, five conclusions may be noted: First, the fact that government fiscal programs in 1963 and 1969 provided net gains to all income classes is well supported by the results of this study. Net benefits for the lowest income class were quite pronounced in 1969 under the money income base, much more so than was the case in 1963. 267 As for the other income classes, the net fiscal in- cidence pattern was still continuously regressive in 1969 under the money income base. But for 1963, under that income base, the trend turned slightly upward at the highest income bracket, thus making the entire fiscal incidence picture ap- pear somewhat U-shaped rather than generally downward sloping, as in 1969. Under an adjusted income base, however, the net fiscal incidence trends in both years were flattened out, as was true of the tax and expenditure incidence patterns. Al- though the regressivity remained under an adjusted income base (at least in 1969), this was again barely apparent. (For 1963 the slope of the generalized net fiscal incidence func- tion even turned slightly positive, meaning that the fiscal system was progressive.) This being the case, it would be best to call the fiscal programs of 1963 and 1969 proportional. But of the two, the 1969 fiscal programs offered greater net benefits to all households relative to their income than did the 1963 programs. Second, the foregoing conclusion that every income class gained absolutely from government tax and expenditure programs is valid only insofar as the budget imbalance, with expenditures exceeding taxes by quite a large amount, is as— sumed to add to the income of households without any cor- responding reduction of real income through possible price increases due to budget deficits. This is known as the post— fisc income distribution under Assumption I. Using Assumption II, that is, if the deficit is eliminated by a hypothetical 268 collection of a proportional income tax, then there were net gainers and net losers. The pattern of post-fisc income dis- tribution was the same as before the elimination of the bud- get deficit, only the level of net fiscal incidence was re- duced. The pattern of income redistribution became easier to see; any income class with a negative effective fiscal rate was said to have redistributed its income to other in- come classes with positive effective fiscal rates. In 1963 the top and the bottom income classes were clearly the net gainers, with the three income groups in between the net losers. In 1969, the redistribution was quite clear-cut, with the first four income brackets being the net gainers, and the last three brackets the net losers. Third, it is possible, and in fact more likely, that the existence of a budget deficit would drive prices up in Thailand. If it is assumed that prices rise to the amount of the deficit, and that the effect is an equal reduction in real income of each household (Assumption III,), then the fiscal programs in 1963 and 1969 would turn mildly progres- sive. In other words, a budget deficit in an overall fiscal program is very important, and different assumptions about its income distributional impact could yield different net fiscal incidence results. Fourth, under Assumptions I and II regarding the bud- get deficit, the 1963 post-fisc income distribution improved over the pre-fisc income distribution of the same year by about 0.8 percent using a money income base, but worsened 269 by about 0.2 percent under an adjusted income base. In 1969, the post-fisc income distribution improved over the pre-fisc income distribution under both income bases, and the rate of improvement ranged from 2.0 to 4.7 percent. But under Assump- tion III, the post-fisc income distribution actually became more unequal than the pre-fisc income distribution in both 1963 and 1969. In 1963 the post-fisc distribution worsened by about 2.3 to 3.8 percent, compared to about 0.6 to 1.2 percent in 1969. Fifth, and most important as a conclusion, the fiscal programs of the government caused very little improvement in the existing income distribution of Thai households. The ef- fects were so minimal that by slightly changing the assumption as to how to allocate the burden of the budget deficit reversed the overall effects from equalizing to de—equalizing income distribution. One brighter note, however, is that the fiscal programs of 1969 were definitely and consistently more income equalizing than those of 1963. This means that the govern- ment's impact on income distribution is becoming more favor- able as time passes. Yet, the fact remains that the rate of improvement over the six years between 1963 and 1969 was still woefully slow and the magnitude of improvement was small. Also, the income redistributional effects of the government taxes and expenditures in 1969 were still much too inadequate to off- set the increased inequality in adjusted income distribution over the previous six years. 270 Policy Implications There are many ways in which the government could change the distribution of income of individuals or house- holds. Taxes and public expenditures are merely one instru- ment of income redistribution, but since this study is con- cerned only with tax and expenditure incidence, it is ap— propriate to consider policy implications only in those areas. No doubt the present findings could have implications in other areas, but a discussion of these issues is outside the scope of this research. On the Tax Side At least five recommendations may be made concerning changes in taxation policy: First, the entire Thai tax system is much too regres- sive. This study has clearly shown how the lower income households have suffered the burdens of regressive taxes re- latively more than upper income households. The main aim of any tax reform should be to reduce the regressivity of the tax and revenue structures as much as possible. Second, and more specifically, reform should be fo~ cused on strengthening income or direct taxation in Thailand. An income tax that contributes only 5 to 6 percent of total government revenues is much too low. The main problem is not so much with the tax rate (although present structures could be improved to make the effective rate more progressive), 271 but with compliance and enforcement. The present tax adminis- tration system must be thoroughly streamlined before tax col- lections can increase. Third, a system of property and wealth taxation must be instituted. It is difficult to believe that in the face of continuing concentration of wealth among a small but grow- ing number of families, Thailand has no estate, gift, or in- heritance taxes. An effective wealth tax, probably both on net wealth as well as transfer tax, would be a most commend- able income redistributing agent in addition to an improved income tax system. Fourth, with increased revenues from direct taxation, the dependence on such indirect taxes as business taxes, se- lective sales taxes, and certain import duties would diminish. Since these indirect taxes burden the poorer income classes relatively more than the wealthier, less dependence on them would certainly improve income equality. Finally, certain taxes are singularly burdensome to the poor, such as the rice premiums and state lotteries. The government favors these revenue sources for their convenience in collection, but they should be abolished if the government is truly concerned with improving the present income distribu- tion. On the Expenditure Side Four recommendations concerning expenditures seem most important: 272 First, expenditure programs as a whole are regressive or pro-poor, and this is desirable. But since a budget defi— cit is probably detrimental to a more equal distribution of income because of inflationary pressure, attempts should be made to have a balanced or near-balanced budget through in- creased direct taxes and a curtailment of certain expenditure items. Second, those expenditures which need to be reduced include defense and public administration. The imputed benefits from these general services constituting 40 to 50 percent of all benefits accruing to the poorest households has a dubious meaning at best. The benefits from a large defense and general administrative spending may be overesti- mated, particularly from the point of View of the poorest households. Third, for income distribution purposes, there is a need for additional spending in primary education and health and public welfare services. Primary schooling in rural Thailand is very underdeveloped. Considering the ever-present budget constraints, emphasis should be placed more on primary than on secondary and highly subsidized university education. Also, an adequate social welfare program should be instituted. At the very least, the already planned but long delayed so- cial security program should be put into operation. Fourth, agricultural expenditures should be increased. The government should be more actively involved in agricultural credit and in provisions for guaranteed prices and in devedoping 273 market outlets. Thai farmers are probably the segment of the population that deserve to be assisted the most in redistrib- uted efforts. The foregoing are some policy implications and recom- mendations stemming from the results of this fiscal incidence study. It is noted again that these policies are confined to the areas of taxes and public expenditures only; there are many other nonbudgetary policies that could conceivably gen- erate a much greater income redistributional impact. Land reform is one example. If a massive land reform were suc- cessfully carried out, it would be certain to improve the distribution of income within the country. Thai farmers con- stitute more than three-quarters of Thailand's population and the majority are in debt.1 Their indebtedness ranges from a fraction of a norman annual crop yield to many times that amount, and within a few years they will lose-the ownership of the land to creditor landlords or money lenders. Many of these farmers are forced into debt through no fault of their own, but because of adverse production and marketing condi- tions, credit conditions, and the general neglect of the government. Suggestions for Further Research This intertemporal study of fiscal incidence in Thai- land is by no means satisfactory in every respect. There are undoubtedly several shortcomings in analysis, statistical data, and in misplaced emphasis. Future research should be conducted 274 with the following possible improvements in mind: (1) Income and expenditure surveys should be carried out frequently, preferably on an annual basis. (2) It is to be hoped that household surveys will become much more reliable as the system is regularized and the researchers become more experienced. In these surveys, an emphasis should be placed on perfecting the income elements, including nonmoney income, on consistency in the methods of eStimation, and in the presentation of the results. (3) Tax and expenditure records should be collected with as much disaggregated detail as possible. The analysis should be expanded from a national level to a regional, sec- toral and provincial level. (4) The practice is becoming widespread of studying in detail, the income distributional effects of specific public expenditures such as those for irrigation and public health. This involves much more than simply assuming who the beneficiaries of such expenditures are, and then allocating those expenditures; actual field studies are necessary in which sample surveys are conducted to determine who receives the benefits and how much, using some index of benefit valua- tion. For example, regarding health expenditures for public hospital operations, income records could be kept of the in- come groups who come for medical service and the amount of services provided. This method of study is very expensive, of course, but it would provide a much clearer idea of the areas to which the government should reorient its policy for 275 equity purposes. (5) If possible, researchers should attempt to in- corporate in their studies the income redistributive in— fluences of the non-budgetary policies and external influences such as the effects of foreign aid and loans. Certainly, this is not the work for one or even a few researchers. Perhaps a government body could be established to deal specifically with this problem of evaluating the income redistributional impact of the entire economic structure. FOOTNOTE S lSee Uthis Narksaward, Report on the Indebtedness and Marketing Practices of Rice Farmers in the Central Plain of Thailand, B. B. 2510-2511. (Bangkok: National Research Council and United States Operation Mission, 1970). 276 APPENDICES APPENDIX A THE ESTIMATION OF THE NUMBER OF HOUSEHOLDS IN 1963 APPENDIX A THE ESTIMATION OF THE NUMBER OF HOUSEHOLDS IN 1963 l. The pOpulation figures by regions taken from the 1960 population census are compared to the population figures by regions taken from the 1970 population and hous- ing census. From the total rate of increase of population in each region over 10 years, the average annual rate of growth is estimated. 2. The population in 1963 by regions and locations is then estimated by raising the 1960 pOpulation by three times the average annual growth rate of population. The result is shown in Table A.l. 3. The average numbers per family by regions (also shown in Table A.1) are obtained from the 1962-1963 House- hold Expenditure Survey, and they were used to divide the population in each corresponding location and region in 1963 to arrive at the number of families by regions. 4. Multiplying these families by the percentage distribution of families by income classes (Table 2.1) and summing up all urban and rural households in all regions resulted in the total number of households, as shown in Table A.2. 277 278 Table A.l--Estimated Population in 1963 (Numbers in Thousands) Regions Urban Rural Total North 855.1 (5.1) 5,397.7 (5.3) 6,252.8 Central-East 1,126.4 (5.3) 5,731.5 (5.6) 6,857.9 Northeast 776.8 (5.4) 9,124.9 (5.9) 9,901.7 South 595.0 (5.6) 2,976.8 (5.2) 3,571.8 Bangkok 2,115.6 (5.5) -- 2,115.6 Whole Kingdom 5,468.9 23,230.9 ‘ 28,699.8 Note: Figure in parenthesis is the size of household in that region and location taken from the Reports of the 1962-1963 Household Expenditure Survey publISHed by the National Statistical Office. 279 Table A.2—-Estimated Number of Households in 1963 (Numbers in Thousands of Households) Incomgagiasses Urban Rural Whole Kingdom % Under 3,000 129.7 2,359.3 2,489.0 48.1 3,000- 5,999 175.2 898.8 1,074.0 20.8 6,000-11,999 336.8 674.1 1,010.9 19.5 12,000-17,999 159.3 141.5 300.8 5.8 18,000-23,999 76.1 49.9 126.0 2.4 24,000-29,999 38.1 12.5 50.6 1.0 30,000-35,999 29.2 8.3 ’37.5 0.7 36,000-47,999 25.3 8.3 33.6 0.7 48,000-59,999 14.1 4.2 18.3 0.4 60,000 and over 29.2 4.2 33.3 0.6 All Classes 1,013.0 4,161.0 5,174.0 100.0 APPENDIX B BASIC INFORMATION FOR THE ESTIMATION OF THE DISTRIBUTION OF MONEY INCOME IN 1969 APPENDIX B BASIC INFORMATION FOR THE ESTIMATION OF THE DISTRIBUTION OF MONEY INCOME IN 1969 Since the basic information for the estimation of the 1969 money income distribution in this study is obtained from the retabulation of the original 1968-1969 socio-econo- mic survey results by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook, the outcome of which differed slightly from the officially published figures, it is necessary that such basic data be provided for the interested reader. 1. Table B.1 shows the number of households in 1969 taken directly from the Repert.gf Population and Housing Census, 1970. Since the census was conducted primarily during 1969, no further adjustment was made to these figures. 2. The distributions of urban and rural households by regions are shown in Table B.2. They provide the weights by which the urban and rural households are subdivided into regions. 3. The distributions of urban and rural households by income classes in each region are available from the 1968- 1969 socio-economic survey (Tables B.3 and 3.4). With these distributions, the number of urban and rural households by income classes in each region can be estimated. 280 281 4. Given the average annual money income by income classes in each region (Tables B.5 and B.6), also available from the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey, the total money income of households by locations, regions, and income classes easily can be computed. Table B.l—-Number of Households in Urban and Rural Areas, 1969 Location figgifggi?s Percentage Urban 762.1 12.9 Rural 5,146.4 87.1 Whole Kingdom 5,908.5 100.0 Source: Thailand, National Statistical Office, Report of Population and Housing Census, 1970 (Bangkok, 1974), Table 2. Table B.2--Percentage Distribution of Urban and Rural Households by Regions, 1969 Region Urban Rural North 11.0 24.9 Central 16.3 23.6 Northeast 10.7 36.4 South 10.8 13.6 Bangkok 51.2 1.5 Total 100.0 100.0 Source: Thailand, National Statistical Office, Report of Socio—Economic Survey, 1968-1969 (Bangkok, 1974), p. 36. 282 Table B.3--Percentage Distribution of Urban Households by Income Classes, 1969 Income Classes Regions (Baht) North Central Northeast South Bangkok Under 3,000 1.5 1.2 1.4 1.2 0.5 3,000- 5,999 12.5 5.0 3.7 6.4 1.2 6,000- 8,999 12.5 7.4 9.6 13.9 4.4 9,000-11,999 16.5 10.5 13.2 14.5 8.9 12,000-14,999 10.6 14.5 11.5 11.9 10.2 15,000-17,999 8.2 11.1 9.4 10.1 9.8 18,000—23,999 14.8 18.2 19.5 14.0 19.8 24,000-29,999 5.4 12.3 10.3 8.8 12.4 30,000-35,999 5.3 5.3 6.1 . 5.4 7.9 36,000-47,999 7.1 4.8 4.2 5.1 9.0 48,000-59,999 1.1 3.4 5.0 3.8 5.6 60,000 and over 4.8 6.3 6.2 5.0 10.4 All Classes 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Results of the retabulation of the original data tapes of the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. 283 Table B.4--Percentage Distribution of Rural Households by Income Classes, 1969 Income Classes Regions (Baht) North Central Northeast South Bangkok Under 3,000 18.4 7.0 52.1 17.2 1.1 3,000- 4,499 19.4 9.7 15.6 19.5 3.1 4,500- 5,999 14.9 9.4 7.3 19.2 5.8 6,000- 7,499 12.3 11.2 5.8 14.2 6.0 7,500— 8,999 8.9 10.6 4.2 8.7 3.2 9,000-10,499 4.9 10.3 4.7 6.2 7.3 10,500-11,999 4.0 6.1 1.1 3.6 6.6 12,000-14,999 7.2 10.2 3.1 3.8 15.3 15,000-17,999 3.8 7.4 1.6 3.0 11.3 18,000-32,999 5.5 12.6 3.4 4.2 24.8 33,000 and over 0.8 5.6 1.1 0.4 15.6 All Classes 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Results of the retabulation of the original data tapes of the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. 284 Table B.5--Average Urban Annual Money Income, by Income Classes, 1969 (Amounts in Baht) Income Classes Regions (Baht) North Central Northeast South Bangkok Under 3,000 2,326 1,578 1,617 1,302 1,747 3,000- 5,999 4,503 4,171 4,265 4,522 4,545 6,000- 8,999 7,530 7,526 7,128 7,192 7,429 9,000-11,999 10,144 10,394 10,302 10,302 10,278 12,000-14,999 13,112 13,244 12,899 13,166 13,216 15,000-17,999 16,182 16,066 16,070 16,324 16,186 18,000-23,999 20,196 20,208 20,117 20,313 20,256 24,000-29,999 25,838 25,650 25,639 25,965 26,303 30,000-35,999 32,286 32,327 32,786 31,871 32,169 36,000-47,999 40,295 40,628 40,664 40,033 40,670 48,000-59,999 53,703 52,035 52,865 53,614 52,705 60,000 and over 115,354 101,226 130,291 126,847 117,123 Average 20,955 24,188 26,213 23,233 32,844 Source: Results of the retabulation of the original data tapes of the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. 285 Table B.6-~Average Rural Annual Money Income, by Income Classes, 1969 (Amounts in Baht) Income Classes Regions (Baht) North Central Northeast South Bangkok Under 3,000 2,078 1,832 1,546 2,125 1,732 3,000- 4,499 3,638 3,674 3,622 3,589 3,694 4,500- 5,999 5,125 5,145 5,160 5,082 5,266 6,000- 7,499 6,491 6,665 6,556 6,682 6,743 7,500- 8,999 8,028 8,188 8,164 8,226 8,013 9,000-10,499 9,699 9,618 9,542 9,688 9,708 10,500-11,999 11,245 11,096 11,081 11,044 11,094 12,000-14,999 13,117 13,087 13,104 13,104 13,403 15,000-17,999 16,083 15,881 16,148 16,097 16,215 18,000-32,999 23,470 22,861 23,058 22,386 23,158 33,000 and over 45,947 60,287 131,372a 51,946 59,824 Average 7,488 13,009 5,963 6,831 21,488 Source: Results of the retabulation of the original data tapes of the 1968-1969 socio-economic survey by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. a . ' Computationally correct figure APPENDIX C THE ESTIMATION OF INCOME IN KIND IN 1963 APPENDIX C THE ESTIMATION OF INCOME IN KIND IN 1963 1. The average income in kind by income classes for 1969 is supplied by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook and is presented in Table C.l. 2. The relationship between "total" income, defined as money income, plus income in kind is established through the following linear regression equation: Y = a + me = u, t where Yt is total income, Ym is money income, a and b are parameters to be estimated, and u is the statistical dis- turbance. The resulting estimates of parameters in the income in kind functions are shown in Table C.2. 3. After substituting the 1963 average monthly money income of each income class from each region and location into the estimating equation, the average income in kind by income classes, locations, and regions is obtained. This estimation uses the average money incomes supplied by Dr. Meesook, not the midpoint incomes, because it is believed that Dr. Meesook's data provide better income variations among regions. It should be mentioned, however, that both estimated total incomes (that is, money income plus income in kind) using both methods are very close to one another. 286 287 4. When the average income in kind is multiplied by the number of households in 1963, the total income in kind for 1963 is obtained,as presented in Table C;3. Table C.l--The Average Income in Kind, by Locations, by Income Classes, 1969 (Amounts in Baht) Incomgaglasses Urban Rural Under 3,000 1,398 2,826 3,000— 5,999 1,221 4,418 6,000- 8,999 742 4,462 9,000-11,999 829 3,851 12,000-14,999 957 2,030 15,000-17,999 1,193 2,202 18,000 and over 8,927 5,140 Source: Basic data supplied by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. I.ll.‘..l'l.l' III!!! I! iuiil Is! Iii!!! .I .I. l.§il II I 288 Table C.2--The Estimated Income in Kind Regression Functions (Yt = a + me + u) Locations and Regions Intercept Slope R2 Urban North 952 .9929 .9995 (6.65) (161.59) Central 927 1.0130 .9995 (4.64) (137.55) Northeast 913 1.0247 .9998 (2.65) (93.34) South 777 1.0234 .9997 (6.80) (234.13) Bangkok 911 1.0063 1.0000 (14.56) (693.43) Rural North 1,776 1.0248 .9907 (12.96) (49.65) Central 1.876 1.0146 .9999 (34.35) (300.10) Northeast 3,477 0.9719 .9988 (63.47) (67.70) South 1,271 1.0520 .9983 (17.74) (86.51) Bangkok 657 1.0286 .9999 (4.53) (214.73) Source: Results supplied by Dr. Oey Astra Meesook of Thammasat University. Note: Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. 289 a.mo~.aa a.amm m.mma a.mma.a a.mao.~ a.mam.a _spamcax mama: m.mam a.mm m.mm a.amm a.mmm a.mmm apnea m.mm~.m a.am m.ma m.aaa m.aaa m.maa.m pmmmnupoz m.aaa m.ma a.am a.mma m.mma a.maa papa a.mma.a a.mm m.aaa a.mam a.mom m.aaa appacmo o.mom.a m.ma a.am m.mmm m.mam m.maa.a 5.82 .mmmmm m.aaa m.aaa a.am m.mma m.ma a.ma xoxmamm m.maa m.mm a.mm m.mm m.aa m.a napoa m.mma m.am m.mm m.ma a.am a.mm ammonuuoz a.mm m.ma m.a a.am m.m m.a pmam m.aaa m.ma a.mm a.mm a.am m.ma amuucmo m.aaa m.ma a.ma a.mm a.am m.ma appoz ammmmm pm>o_a:a mmm.ma mmm.aa mmm.a moo.m 8830 momma -ooo.ma name .a .68 .m 88: 898m a8 8883 aaa 35mm: monumau m.a—08a 328 a0 appaaaaz ca 8885 mama 65.2 :a 9:85 HBOBIIM .U 0....nt [I'llII'llli ll“ APPENDIX D DISTRIBUTIVE SERIES FOR USE AS TAX AND EXPENDITURE ALLOCATION BASES APPENDIX D DISTRIBUTIVE SERIES FOR USE AS TAX AND EXPENDITURE ALLOCATION BASES This appendix describes how each allocation base from the distributive series table was obtained. This information will enable the interested reader to retrace the steps taken in estimating the final tax and expenditure incidence in this study. Tables D.l and D.2 Base Bl-B8: For 1963 these distributions of house- hold expenditures are computed by multiplying the average monthly expenditures by families on eight commodity groups (shown in Tables 4.3 and 4.4 in the 1962-1963 Household Expenditure Survey) by the number of households in the corresponding income brackets (see Appendix A). The eight commodity groups are listed in greater detail as follows: (1) food purchased and prepared at home as well as food consumed away from home; (2) housing, furnishing, and house- hold operations; (3) clothing and materials; (4) transporta- tion; (5) reading, recreation, and education; (6) medical and personal care; (7) tobacco and alcoholic drinks; and (8) gifts and contributions, taxes, and miscellaneous house— hold expenses. The percentage share of expenditures of each income class in each commodity group is then computed from the total 290 “mocmucooummv mwmfl .mmfiumvm m>flusfiuuwwflllwd wanna. 291 0.006 0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 x2. 885 666385 mm 0.006 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.0 0.0 macfigm 698598 mm 0.03 0.2 0.3 0.00 04 0.0 3.60606 60.885 6 0.03 m.mm m.m 0K m0 0.0 38036 56.0.6965 0N 0.006 0.00 0.3 0.00 0.3 0.0 36.80 6896 no 9586 2 0.006 0.2 a.mm 0.2 0.0m 0.00 6805 mo 9.8.66.6 3 0.03 0.3 0.: 0.: 6.6 a.mm 2.096 9.66 S 0.03 0.5 0.2 0.2 m.m m.a .885 :35 m: 0.03 m.mm 6.2 0.00 0.3 0.2 9805 638. 2 0.03 0.00 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 anew 9.85 08. S 0.02 6.0 0.0 0.3 0.60 0.00 39688 6.56 3 0.006 0.0m 0.3 m.mm 0.: m.ma 328:8 635 NH 002 m.m m.m 0.3 0.00 6.00 Batman 38. d 0.03 m.mm 566 0.00 0.3 0.0m .96 086.82 638 S 0.02 m.ma 0.: 0.0m 0.: 0.00 .96. 38. 0 0.006 0.00 0.: 0.6 0.3 a.mm .96 BBSSmBE 0 0.006 0.06 0.2 0.0m 0.: 0.0m .96 088.8. a 0.03 0.2 0.: m.mm 0.2 0.00 .96 88 68:82 0 0.03 0.: 0.3 m.mm 0.2 0.2 .96 838686 0 0.006 m.mm m.ma 0.0m m.ma 0.3 .96 cflumfi&mcg 0 0.006 0.2 0.: 0.0m 0.5 0.00 .96 054.68 m 0.03 m.mm 0.2 0.00 0.3 0.00 .96 96.0.8: 0 0.006 0.3 . 0.3 0.00 0.3 «:00 .96 88 H “68.6% 000.2 000”: 000mm 000.0 mmMmU 000 2 -000 NH -000 0 -000 m 365 mcoflsflfifla mmmm same .6688 285 36935869 83 63.86 ggflmfloia .o magma Table D.2-Distributive Series, 1969 (Percentages) 292 g ooooooooooooooooooooooo I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I H ooooooooooooooooooooooo 21:3 ooooooooooooooooooooooo a HHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHH 33:! 80 HOhNNhomvoocooonomxoONomxoh-zr I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I ~ mmgamvaHv-u'mcoONNthMNNm 3g mq mmmmmvwam gunmen Ncommm I cm 83 onmoommxomvxococooooxovoom—ivwa ~~ hhmhmmmhhhvmmowmhhvaHN ml‘ H 01.4 .4.—a I cm :3 83: LONQ'HmNmFVQ‘mMHOHNmNKDu-immrv I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I .. mmmmmmmmmmmamommmehvhha Nv H H o-n-I .4.-4 V m 0 I m cm :3 8g manhmmwmmomomONommHhNNm I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 8 .~ :mdmhaomoom—amomvHNwavo as: .4.-4 .4.-1 .4.—4H NN 8 u '5 83 moomuoooooNNxobommoxomoooxohNNo I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I om mdmahwmmNHmhhoov-«moomvvo .. .-c .4.-4 .4.-1 Hr-JI-l .-I Hv-IN .4.-4 moo $3: \omomNNmNoohoomooomxoxoq-vmooo I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I can NOMFWMHQHOMMkDOO‘OMNMOOOO ~~ .4.-4H .4.-4 l—‘I—IN N Pit-FIN mm o 8 HammmhommoammOhr-uooocoq—«oo I I o I 0 O 0 0 O o o I I I I a I I I I I I I I . (\RDBMNNBIDKDKDQ'OI‘OMOMOQOOOO m N N m Distributions Recreation musing Exp. Clothing Exp. 'Ibtal Non-food Ekp. Transportation Exp. Medical Care Exp. Tobacco Exp. Miscellaneous Ebcp. Total Household Urban Household ‘Ibtal Exp. Rural Household Food Exp. 'Ibp Inoane Group Total Income Urban Imone Rural Income Ihciprocal of Incrme Incane of Rubber Growers University Students '13 1c1a Government Off Government Pensmners Individual Income Tax 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 12 13 ll 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 293 0.000.60 0000.0 0.0000 0.00006 0000.0 0.006.66 006360696 6596. 0000.0 0000.6 0.060 0.000 0.0.00 0000.6 00866668002 0.0006 0.060 0.060 0.000 0.060 0.000 8930.6. 0000.0 0.060 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 88 680066 0.0006 0.000 0.600 0.000 0.000 0.000 8068.680 0.0006 0.000 0 .000 0. 600 0.060 0.000 . 86636960566. 0000.0 0.0066 0.000 0.0006 0.0066 0.0006 055060 0000.0 0060.6 0.000 0.0006 0.000 0.0006 0:608: 0.000.06 0000.0 0000.6 0006.0 0000.0 0000.0 6.86 608 0% 000.06 000.66 000.0 000.0 8mm6m6o 000.06 000.06 000.0 000.0 6.00:0 00:80 06.602660 3.6000 8000.600 058:6 3:06 00 0866662 :6 065050 0006 .86660896 069606566 0396.10.06 06060.6. 294 m.amv.mm m.ovN.vN mNomJV 0.53:.“ m.mamfi 0.0.3.0. a.ammb 06.3.0” mmflflfig H638. H.th.v v.mmv.N 0.60m H.090 m.mmm mNmm . 60.va N.NmN gaqmaawomfiz v.mmH.m N.NMN.H otnmN Whom H.Nvm 5.5.3 m.abm qtnNN 00038 a.mooJ a.ammra waN m.mmm m.amv H..Hmm mKom o.o....m 6.6.600 H6003 «.mmmN mwaJ m.vON a.amN mNmH m.aaa Emma 03mm 8388a m.mmvfi .70th .H.NvN 0.3.0” m.mmm H.No¢ mJKN m.ONH . 833.609.008.69 m.mmm6 m.mmvN N630 0.0mm vinNh Ndvm 9th a.mov 9.6.0.508 0.935 m.mme m.amw ._...wvm w.omm N.mo~. m.mvw mNmM 96.09603 m.mmH.mN m.mmn.oa v.mma.~ 0.2.9N m.mmN.m mNmfim v.mmm.m m.NHo.N 08h .695 Em mmmKH mmmJH mmmJa mmm.m mmmfi ooo.m mmmmdau ooo.ma Iooofia loco.NH I255 I256 A508 .6865 @9566 03.69500 H2 Augmmv mmmmMHU mag 35606 no 665.0302 660 3030.56; $00 566503 365090: 33:05 6360.6. '— ‘ _ _ ‘ .-— ‘— A _ I A (ann‘ exaC' hous‘ in T. Surv. Tabl¢ in l! exper exper in Ta hold numbe is ob total rural fOr l the ix highe: frOm T 295 (annual) expenditures, as shown in Table D.3. For 1969, exactly the same procedure is used. The average monthly household expenditures for eight commodity groups are given in Table 4 in the Report of the 1968-1969 Socio-Bconomic Survey, and the number of households in 1969 in given in Table 2.6 in the text. Table D.4 shows total expenditures in 1969. Base B9: The distribution of total household expenditures is estimated by multiplying the average total expenditures, by locations, by income classes (also shown in Tables 4.3 and 4.4 in the 3gport of the 1962-1963 House- hold Expenditure Survey: Whole Kingdom)turthe corresponding numbers of households (Table A.2). Base 310: The distribution of nonfood expenditures is obtained from the total household expenditures after the total food expenditures by income classes are subtracted. Base 811-313: For 1963, the distribution of urban, rural, and total households is obtained from Appendix A: for 1969, it is obtained from Tables 2.4 to 2.6 in the text. Base B14: This distribution is used in cases where the incidence is assumed to fall entirely on the top or the highest income group. Base 815-817: For both 1963 and 1969, the distribu- tions of urban, rural, and total money income are obtained from Tables 2.3, 2.4, and 2.5 in the text. for recig this the I prod' nunum enabi by s: then The a into is as remai Patte inconm entitl Univer Thamma: Student their P fOr 197 296 Base 818: The total money income in each income class for 1963 and 1969 .ns reciprocated. The share of the recuxocated sum by each income class is then estimated to give this distribution. Base 819: The 1963 Agricultural Census conducted by the National Statistical Office contains information on the production of rubber by size of holdings and also the total number of rubber growing households by size of holdings. This enables one to compute the total volume of rubber production by size of holdings for 1963. The average rubber price is then used to convert it to total income by size of holdings. The average income of rubber growers is then adjusted to fit into the income class classification for 1963. For 1969, it is assumed that the distribution of income of rubber growers remains the same as in 1963, so the 1963 distributional pattern is used. Base B20: The distribution of university students by income classes for 1963 and 1969 :hs obtained from the report entitled General Facts about First-Year Students at Thammasat University! 1972-1973, published by Thammasat University. It is assumed, first, that the distribution of Thammasat students is representative of all other university students with respect to the overall income positions of their parents and, second, that the pattern of distribution for 1973-1974 is the same for 1963 and 1969. This second fc by Se: F01 she the to mil. the Sim; lowe mOVe in t in t: It i: Pensj the E deCid perCeJ 297 assumption tends to bias in favor of the lower income classes because the current pattern is for these lower income classes to be able to attend universities which they could not attend ten years ago. But this bias should not unduly affect the pattern of benefits received since expenditures for higher education are quite small. Base 821-822: The distribution of government officials by size of salaries was obtained directly from the State Service Commission and the Department of Comptroller General. For distribution in 1969, one might notice a small percentage share in the lowest income class. This was the result of the program set up by the Department of Local Government to hire some villagers to perform the duty of village militiamen, for which each was paid a small fee. Thus the distribution of government pensioners was estimated simply by deleting the number of official households in the lowest salary bracket. It is recognized that officials do move up the income scale when they retire, but most remain in the middle income brackets because the promotion system in the Thai bureaucracy is, by and large, extremely slow. It is possible to obtain the actual distribution of goverment pensioners for 1963 and 1969 by reconstructing data from the Department of the Comptroller General, but it was decided that this was not worth the time and effort. Base B23: This distribution in fact shows the percentage of income tax that has been paid by households in various mnlin in the . These t4 into the For 1961 that the approxir 298 various income brackets. For 1969 the statistics on indivi— dual income tax returns by size of taxable incomeannapresented in the 1969 annual report of the Department of Revenue. These taxable income brackets have been rearranged to fit into the income class classification used in this study. For 1963, there are no similar statistics, so it is assumed that the pattern of income tax burden for 1963 is approximately the same as for 1969. APPENDIX E DISAGGREGATED TAX DATA Tab} APPENDIX E DISAGGREGATED TAX DATA Table E.1--Disaggregated Taxes and Other Revenues, 1963 and 1969 (Amounts in Millions of Baht) Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 1. Individual income tax 468.2 1,119.5 2. Corporate income tax classified by the following types of business activities: 312.2 851.1 2.1 Agriculture, forestry, fishery 2.4 2.7 2.2 Mining 40.6 17.2 2.3 Construction and repair 5.7 20.5 2.4 Manufacturing 81.7 291.7 Food 1.6 47.4 Softdrink and beer 11.2 -- Alcoholic drinks 7.3 14.8 Cement and cement products 36.2 59.9 Wood products '-- 21.5 Cosmetic and leather products -- 53.7 Glass 7.0 10.7 Other 18.4 83.6 2.5 Public Utilities and Transport 17.7 38.9 Public transport 16.5 38.1 Water and light 1.2 0.8 2.6 Commerce 97.4 306.9 Export-import 31.2 80.1 Hardware and dep't stores -- 80.6 Other 50.7 146.2 2.7 Banking, insurance, real estate 31.6 79.7 299 300 Table E.1--continued Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 2.8 Other services 32.2 33.3 Service stations 19.6 -- Other 12.6 -- 2.9 Other miscellaneous 2.7 60.2 3. Selective sales taxes 400.5 2,521.1 Entertainment taxes 47.6 85.6 Liquor 194.4 299.7 Beer 41.5 190.7 Non-alcoholic beverages 42.5 126.5 Matches 20.8 24.2 Tobacco 30.0 738.5 Cement 16.5 45.2 Snuff 6.6 10.8 Oil and fuel -- 999.7 Other 0.5 0.1 4. Business taxes 1,561.3 3,490.5 4.1 Sales type A ’928.3a 1,622.3 List 1 1,393.4 Food, drinks, and tobacco 473.0 Clothing 105.1 Cosmetics and medicine 115.2 Building materials and stationery 221.6 Household tools and utensils 40.8 Motor vehicles 61.1 Fuel, oi1,and petroleum products 235.3 Sundry goods 84.8 Miscellaneous 56.5 List 2 134.0 Food 2.4 Household goods 22.0 Machinery 5.2 Other 104.4 301 Table E.1--continued Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 List 3 94.9 Upland crOp export 94.9 4.2 Sales type B 265.0 663.9 Refrigerators, air condi- tioners 18.6 8.0 Electrical appliances 0.6 36.0 Passenger cars 15.1 144.9 Liquor 79.2 308.2 Painted material 1.9 3.8 Gold and jewelry 7.2 14.0 Tin and rubber exports 126.6 135.4 Other (food) 15.8 13.6 4.3 Rice and saw milling 124.9 223.7 4.4 Contractor and services 89.0 439.1 Printing 4.2 14.0 Photographic shOps 2.5 4.2 Civil construction 33.4 247.5 Advertising ' 1.9 14.7 Barbershops, beauty salons 1.7 4.5 Other 45.3 154.3 4.5 Rental services 3.0 17.1 4.6 Storage services 0.8 3.1 4.7 Hotels and restaurants 49.6 135.4 Nightclubs 5.2 12.6 Hotels 13.6 57.9 Restaurants 30.8 64.9 4.8 Transport services 14.4 48.9 4.9 Pawnshops 3.0 8.0 4.10 Underwriters, auctioneers 37.5 68.8 4.11 Real estate agencies 0.9 32.1 302 Table E.1--continued Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 4.12 Banking and insurance 39.0 204.5 4.13 Net detail given -- 22.3 4.14 Other 5.9 1.3 5. Import duties 2,764.3 5,294.0 5.1 Food 247.1 369.5 5.2 Drinks and tobacco 116.3 280.2 5.3 Raw materials 19.0 57.3 Wood fiber 0.7 5.6 Clothing fiber 4.8 20.9 Fertilizer 5.7 13.7 Metal and other raw materials 7.7 17.1 5.4 Fuel, oi1,and petroleum products 661.4 434.3 5.5 Animal and vegetable fats 3.5 8.3 5.6 Chemical products 236.9 ‘570.4 Chemical compounds 49.1 100.4 Dye 35.0 74.3 Pharmaseutical products 42.0 68.1 Perfumes 51.9 101.1 Other 58.9 226.4 5.7 Manufactured goods 732.0 1,512.8 Clothes 396.7 625.1 Leather products 1.6 6.3 Wood and cork products 2.0 6.2 Rubber products 77.6 115.3 Paper - 40.1 186.3 Non-metallic products 38.0 82.9 Silver and alloys 3.8 9.0 Other metal products 172.2 481.6 303 Table E.1--continued Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 5.8 Machinery and transport equipment 597.0 1,675.4 Heavy machinery 182.5 450.8 Electrical generators 130.4 376.9 Transport equipment 284.1 847.8 5.9 Miscellaneous manufactured goods 139.6 362 2 Household fixtures 11.8 23.6 Furniture 3.4 8.7 Travel goods 1.9 5.9 Clothing 28.8 55.9 Shoes 2.7 7.6 Scientific equipment, films, and watches 32.5 88.2 Other 58.6 172.4 5.10 Others not included elsewhere 11.5 23.6 6. Rice premiums 798 4 1,235.6 7. Other export taxes 363.2 424.3 Rice 154.5 157.4 Rubber 187.0 227.9 Wood 9.4 19.9 Rawhide 4.7 1.1 Other 7.6 18.0 8. Taxes on property 147 4 390.1 Motor vehicles and automobiles 88.6 214.7 Immovable property registration 58.8 175.5 9. Royalties and permits 422.0 691.9 9.1 Royalties 173.3 354.1 Bird's nest 1.1 2.3 Fishery 6.0 3.5 Wood 5.0 6.8 Other forest products 39.0 46.5 Tin 122.3 294.9 304 Table E.1--continued Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 9.2 Permits 248.7 337.7 Radio 0.5 0.5 Liquor sale 3.1 2.0 Other excise 3.4 8.1 Forest 1.6 7.3 Rubber 20 7 8.4 Alien registration 83.2 63.5 Lottery sale 75.0 118.1 Gambling 48.5 106.9 Gun and fireworks 8.6 14.1 Civil 2.9 4.2 Health 1.3 4.8 10. Government sales and services 322.0 316.1 10.1 Estate sale 0.8 0.3 10.2 National products sale 6.9 5.5 Fuel and oil 5.5 0.4 Wood products 0.7 3.5 Agricultural products '0.6 1.7 10.3 Public utilities 28.1 -- 10.4 Books and documents 0.3 0.6 10.5 Other sales 13.1 43.0 10.6 Services (fees) 221.3 204.8 Customs 6.0 5.7 Animal epidemic control 6.8 5.6 Watergate 8.7 10.8 Land and water transport 7.1 24.7 Fishing 0.6 0.4 Forest conservation 39.0 57.5 Airport tax 6.1 14.3 Vehicles 5.0 11.0 Land fees 3.3 6.2 Mineral fees 0.5 1.1 Weighting fees 7.8 16.3 Others 130.4 51.3 305 Table E.1--continued Year Tax and Revenue Categories 1963 1969 10.7 Rents 51.6 61.6 11. Government monOpolies 776.1 605.3 Contributions from tobacco monopoly 733.8 450.0 Lottery Bureau 40.8 149.7 Other 1.5 5.5 12. State enterprises 226.3 636.4 13. Other Revenues 245.4 949.3 13.1 Fines and surcharges 110.7 152.9 Surcharges 32.5 51.2 Liquor fines 42.2 32.1 Tax fines 6.2 6.1 Other fines 29.8 63.4 13.2 Returned funds 39.4 603.2 13.3 Miscellaneous 99.2 193.2 Interest 5.2 23.7 Mint receipts 47.8 61.0 Other 46.2 108.5 TOTAL 8,807.3 18,525.2 Sources: Compiled from the following publications: Department of Revenue: (1) Annual Report, 1969, (2) Corporate Tax Statistics, 1963 and 1968, (3) Business Taxes Statistics, 1962 and 1969: Budget Bureau: (1) Annual Budget, 1965 and 1971, (2) Government Receipts, 1963 and 1969; Department of Comptroller General, Report of Receipts and Outlays of the Kingdom of Thailand, 1963 and 1969. Note: Disaggregated figures for corporate and business taxes are adjusted from the only partially complete data available from the Department of Revenue. a . Details are too fragmented to be presented here. APPENDIX F DISAGGREGATED PUBLIC EXPENDITURE DATA APPENDIX F DISAGGREGATED PUBLIC EXPENDITURE DATA Table F.1--Disaggregated Public Expenditures, 1963 and 1969 (Amounts in Millions of Baht) 10C Year Expenditure Categories 1963 1969 1. Economic Services 2,560.1 5,962.4 1.1 Agriculture 776.7 2,222.6 General irrigation services 64.9 234.2 Canals and maintenance 88.5 257.7 State irrigation construction 63.7 664.0 General irrigation construction 55.3 245.6 Chao Phya DevelOpment Scheme 65.1 -- Big dam construction 213.6 152.2 OUS: M. Agricultural 6.5 35.2 D. Agricultural 41.3 78.6 D. Rice 33.9 46.0 D. Fishery 26.6 66.2 D. Livestock 36.9 74.4 D. Forestry 72 6 184.7 D. Agricultural Extension -- 80.8 Rubber Organization 7.7 8.0 Rubber Growing Support Fund -- 15.0 Farmers' Assistance Fund -- 80.0 Power and Fuels 271 8 286.1 Atomic Power for Peace Office 3.0 6.3 National Power Commission 29.7 103.5 Provincial Electricity Authority 49.6 45.1 Northeast Electricity Authority - 22.5 Lignite Authority 36.6 11.3 Yankee Electricity Authority 67.8 -- Refinery I (Fang) 19.1 11.7 Refinery II (Bangchak) 3.0 85.6 Metropolitan Electricity Authority 63.0 -- Table F.1--continued 307 Expenditure Categories 1.3 1.4 1.5 Other Economic Services Industries OUS: M. D. Industrial Promotion Industries D. Industrial Works Frozen Food Organization Tannery Organization Textile Organization Glass Organization Thai Paper Factory D. Mineral Resources Board of Investment Jute Mills Tin Buffer Stock Sugar Office Battery Organization Preserved Food Organization Ceramic Factory Thai Rubber Company Sugar Industry Company cation OUS: M. Transportation and Communi- Communication D. Land Transport D. Civil Aviation D. Harbor D. Post and Telegraph D. Highways Port Authority State Railways Telephone Authority Express Transport Organi— zation Thai Shipping Company Thai Television Company Bangkok Dock Company Thai Airways OUS: M. National Develop— ment Year 1963 1969 179.3 173.1 2.4 7.2 3.4 17.3 1.3 14.0 7.0 6.9 0.6 -- 41.2 -- 7.9 -- 0.5 -- 38.2 73.3 -- 3.1 -- 12.0 -- 37.5 -- 1 5 2.5 -- 41.0 -- 0.3 -- 3.0 -- 30.0 -- 26.1 24.3 88.7 19.2 -- 198.8 6.7 36.5 95.0 59.0 758.6 2,550.9 24.6 21.9 32.3 46.4 34.0 -- 9.0 -- 2.6 -- 1.0 -- -- 2.6 0.7 -- 253.1 320.8 308 Table F.1-—continued Year Expenditure Categories D. Soil Development -- D. Credit and Marketing Co-operatives 6 D. Co—operative Auditing 5. Board of Export Promotion 0 Tourist Organization 6 Fish Marketing Organization -- D. Land Co-operatives 50.0 6 Bank of Agricultural and Agricultural Co-operatives -- 140 0 National Economic Promotion Company 146.0 -- Union Hotel Company 13.6 -- 2. Educational Services 1,777.5 3,674.3 2.1 Primary Education 1,024.7 1,997.9 D. Primary Education 1,024.7 208.6 Grants to Provincial Administrations -- 1,789.3 2.2 Secondary Education 234.9 405.0 D. Secondary Education 234.9 405.0 2.3 Higher Education 193.8 559.6 Chulalongkorn 42.8 108.0 Thammasat 14.2 25.8 Kasetsant 18.7 66.1 Mahidol 112.8 170.4 Chiengmai -- 71.0 Silpakorn 5.4 23.0 Khonkaen -- 29.0 NIDA -- 15.4 Songkhla -- 51.0 2.4 Vocational Education and Other 324.0 711.6 D. Vocational Education 115.1 406.7 D. Physical Education 21.8 12.5 OUS: M. Education 76.2 68.5 309 Table F.1--continued Expenditure Categories Year 1969 3. 4. Royal Institute National Education Council D. Teacher Training ' D. Educational Techniques D. Fine Arts National Research Council National Sport Promotion Organization Health and Social Welfare 3.1 Public Health OUS: M. Public Health D. Medicine D. Health D. Medical Science 3.2 Public Welfare D. Public Welfare D. Religious Affairs D. Labor Government Pawn ShOps Government Pensions 3.3 Other Social Services D. Public Works MetrOpolitan Water Work D. Community Development D. Science Zoo Organization Town Planning Office Accelerated Rural DeveloP- ment Office General Services 4.1 Defense M. Defense National Security Council com-heave combat-alum HM 929.3 2,338.0 305.3 619.2 24.1 27.7 153.4 317.0 120.1 266.5 7.6 8.1 443.6 747.8 73.3 170.8 15.4 24.8 '-- 16.8 8.0 -- 347.0 535.3 180.4 971.0 143.8 432.3 -- 165.4 25.1 84.4 6.9 11.1 1.0 1.1 3.7 12.1 -- 264.6 1,637.6 3,718.9 1,637.2 3,716.8 0.4 2.1 310 Table F.1--continued Year Expenditure Categories 1963 1969 4.2 Law Enforcement 797.9 1,558.4 M. Justice 66.3 82.2 D. Correction 95.8 153.0 D. Public Prosecution 24.4 33.6 D. Police 611.3 1,289.6 Public Administration 1,414.6 3,063.8 OUS: Prime Minister's Office 3.8 5.4 Office of the Prime Minister 44.4 28.7 Budget Bureau 3.2 10.8 Office of the Cabinet Secretariat 3.5 5.4 Tax Supervision Office 5.5 10.2 National Economic Develop- ment Board 116.2 7.8 Office of Judicial Council 2.0 2.8 State Service Commission 25.4 44.7 Audit Office 10.9 16.4 National Statistical Office 10.7 32.9 D. Public Relations 35.9 47.6 D. Central Intelligence 7.9 16.5 D. Meteorology 6.3 18.1 OUS: M. Economic Affairs 7.6 16.0 D. Internal Trade 2.8 6.0 D. Foreign Trade 3.2 5.0 D. Business Intelligence 2.5 5.4 D. Trade Registration 3.7 5.3 D. Economic Relations 13.5 9.7 OUS: M. Interior 46.5 47.4 D. Land 42.3 85.8 D. Local Government 429.6 917.6 OUS: M. Finance 47.9 340.0 D. Treasury . 57.7 54.8 D. Comptroller-General 22.7 33.9 D. Customs 38.6 69.5 D. Excise 49.1 63.6 D. Revenue 62.2 103.9 M. Foreign Affairs 86.9 139.3 D. Technical and Economic Co-operation 53.9 445.9 Royal Household Office 26.9 50.1 311 Table F.1--continued Year Expenditure Categories 1963 1969 Royal Privy Council 0.6 1.2 Parliament Secretariat 14.6 24.9 Postal Charges 3.5 8.0 Foreign Training 3.0 0.5 Foreign Conferences 14.4 17.3 Government Official Assistance Fund 101.8 297.2 Phones and Television Charges 3. 11.0 Office of Fiscal Policy -- 57.3 4.4 Other 172.1 795.1 Reserve Fund 172.1 762.7 Counterpart Fund -- 32.5 5. Payments on Public Debt 1,139.4 1,245.5 5.1 Repayments 763.7 217.6 5.2 Interest and Management Fees 375.8 1,027.9 TOTAL 10,502.5 22,904.3 Sources: Compiled from the following publications: National Note: Statistical Office, 1965 and 1971; Statistical Yearbook of Thailand, Department of Comptroller General, Report of Receipts and Outlays of the Kingdom of Thailand, 1963 and 1969. OU M D S = Office of the Under-Secretary Ministry Department APPENDIX G THE LORENZ FUNCTIONS OF VARIOUS DISTRIBUTIONS OF INCOME APPENDIX G THE LORENZ FUNCTIONS OF VARIOUS DISTRIBUTIONS OF INCOME As noted in Chapter 2, a part of the main procedure in this study was to estimate the Lorenz (curve) functions that would fit the pre-fisc, post-tax, post-benefit, post-fisc, and a few other variations of income distributions for 1963 and 1969 so that the exact Gini concentration ratios for both years could be estimated. This method was adopted from N. P. Kakwani and N. Podder as presented in "Efficiency Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Associated Inequality Measures from Grouped Observations," World Bank Development Research Center Discussion Paper No. 10, October 1974 (mimeographed). The function of the desired Lorenz curve is a double-log regression equation of the following form: log [2:3] = a' +alog[m] +Blog [/2-m]+u, .5 5 .5 where p and q are the cumulative prOportions of households and income by income classes, respectively: a',a , and g are the parameters to be estimated; and u is the stochastic disturbance term. The ordinary least—squares method is used to obtain various Lorenz functions. The parameter values and the resulting Gini coefficients (G) are presented in Tables 6.1 and G.2. 312 313 Table G.l--Lorenz Functions of various Distributions of Income, 1963 Distributions . —2 of Income a a B R’ G Pre—Fisc: Money -.2238 1.0281 '.9817 1.0000 .5627 (-57.95) (58.16) (477.71) PreéFisc: Adjusted -.2692 1.2677 .9793 1.0000 .4559 (-38.30) (34.60) (250.86) Post—Tax: Money -.2021 .9538 .9842 1.0000 .6102 (-51.98) (56.70) (484.73) Post-Tax: Adjusted -.2650 1.2654 .9803 1.0000 .4605 (-37.90) (34.87) (252.95) Post-Benefit: Money -.2359 1.0888 .9809 1.0000 .5304 (-50.00) (48.55) (385.79) Post-Benefit: Adjusted -.2709 1.2747 .9792 1.0000 .4529 (-37.61) (33.83) (244.45) PostéFisc: Money -.2218 1.0465 .9828 1.0000 .5581 (Assumptions I & II) (-47.90) (49.07) (398.40) PostéFisc: Adjusted —.2674 1.2734 .9800 1.0000 .4566 (Assumptions I & II) (-37.15) (33.95) (245.31) PostrFisc: Money -.2092 1.0110 .9846 1.0000 .5838 (Assumption III) (-48.86) (52.80) (436.42) Post-Fisc: Adjusted -.2610 1.2579 .9810 1.0000 .4660 (Assumption III) (-37.96) (35.47) (258.09) Note: Figures in parentheses are t—values. 314 Table G.2--Iorenz FUnctions of Various Distributions of Income, 1969 Distributions . —2 of Income a a B R G Pre-Fisc: Money -.2400 .9775 .9760 1.0000 .5550 (-125.69) (836.38) (849.34) Pre-Fisc: Adjusted -.3082 .9616 .9581 (.9998 .4822 (-28.90) (147.62) (148.49) Post-Tax: Money -.2147 .9834 .9825 1.0000 .5847 (-58.41) (436.66) (445.03) Post—Tax: Adjusted -.3085 .9616 .9579 .9998 .4819 (-26.99) (137.74) (138.54) Post-Benefit: aney -.2617 1.0156 .9720 1.0000 .5151 (-77.33) (102.27) (552.29) Post-Benefit: Adjusted -.2972 1.0456 .9644 .9998 .4738 (-26.92) (31.09) (165.17) PosteFisc: Money -.2536 1.0144 .9740 1.0000 .5289 (Assumptions I & II) (~72.11) (98.97) (534.58) Post-Fisc: Adjusted -.2977 1.0487 .9644 .9998 .4725 (Assumptions I & II) PostéFisc: Mbney -.2328 .9860 .9780 1.0000 .5614 (Assumption III) (-92.95) (138.99) (762.41) PostrFisc: Adjusted -.2881 1.0368 .9663 .9999 .4853 (Assumption III) (-24.55) (29.28) (156.30) Note: Figures in parentheses are t-values. APPENDIX H THE NET FISCAL INCIDENCE BASED ON AARON-MCGUIRE-MAITAL METHOD APPENDIX H THE NET FISCAL INCIDENCE BASED ON AARON-MCGUIRE-MAITAL METHOD Dissatisfied with the arbitrary ways in which public expenditures were allocated among income classes in most fiscal incidence studies, Henry Aaron and Martin McGuire prOposed a theory indicating the proper way in which such public good expenditures should be allocated.1 Essentially, they contend that the imputed benefits of public goods provided by the public sector accruing to each family should be determined by some value of private good benefits received by that particular household. A brief description of the Aaron-McGuire theory is given below. In a neoclassical framework of efficient consumption, Aaron and McGuire assume that a utility function for each family is known or can be determined and is a function of the value of private goods and pure public goods in the form vi = f[(Yi + yi) p] D S I I where U1 is the utility of family i: (Y; + Y;) is the summa- tion of disposable income of and the benefits from specific good expenditures received by family i (together, it is the estimated value of private goods consumed by family 1 alone): and P is the amount of public goods. A public good, P, has all the characteristics well known in the literature, for example, it 315 316 is consumed in equal amounts byall, consumption by one has no effect on consumption by others, and no one can be excluded from enjoying it. Aaron and McGuire also assume that the utilities of public goods and other goods are independent. For any two families a and b, the optimal or efficient condition for consumption is attained when the marginal rate of substitution of total private goods and public goods of family a is equal to the similar marginal rate of substitution of family b, that is, when a a a b MRSa = dY /dP = fp/f = EX MRSb dYb/dP fb/fb fa P Y Y where f2, the first partial derivative of Ua with respect to P, is assumed equal maf:,or when MRSaf; = MRSb b = . . . = Y MRSif; = K is a constant. Then assuming that each family's marginal rate of substitution between public goods and other goods is known and that the total and marginal cost of public and specific goods nsknown for all relevant outputs of these goods, for a bundle of public goods to be efficiently shared by all families, it is required that XMRSl where Yp is the total public good benefits (which are equal to the actual public good expenditures), and Y; is the imputed 317 public good benfits accruing unfamily i. As only the ratios of MRS's matter, ZMRSl can be set equal to 1 so that Y1 = Y MRSl = Y —E— = Y —i— , p p E> f1 E> f1 y Y What this equation has shown is that "to each household should be imputed a function of the total value of the public good proportional to the reciprocal of its marginal utility of private good expenditures."2 Aaron and McGuire then specify f; on the basis of dis- posable cash income (or the original income net of tax burdens) plus the estimated value of specific goods received, or Y: + Y; = Y1. Then two utility functions are assumed U1 = A log Y1 + B (1) u1 = E - J%7 (2) Y where A, B, C, and D are arbitrary constants. Differentiating these utility functions with respect to Y1, equations (1) and (2) become dUl/le n H1 k: w- ? A/Y ; (3) P. dUi/in C/Y. . (4) ll H1 L< I 318 If utility function (2) is used,the imputed public good benfits to family i would be that is, the public good expenditures should be allocated to family i according to its proportionate share in the total money income net of tax plus the estimated value of specific good benefits. The above condition implies that the higher the income position of a family, the higher the public good benefits it will receive, other things being equal. Aaron and McGuire believe that the marginal utility of income (for the United States) lies between -1 and -2. Shlomo Maital in a subsequent study further claimed that from at least three independent studies on the marginal utility of income there is valid reason to believe that the value of the "true" marginal utility is -1.5.3 So, in order to determine the net fiscal inci- dence in Thailand using time Aaron—McGuire-Maital (A-M-M) method, the 1969 fiscal activities based on money income distribution are selected as an example. First, the relevant tax burdens are deducted from each income class to arrive at the distribution of disposable income in the Aaron—McGuire sense. Then, the benefits of specific expenditures by income classes (rearranged from Chapter 4 by exchanging such public goods as defense, public administration, and other similar categories) are added to disposable 319 income to arrive at the total private good income distribution, which will be the base for public good benefit allocation. The marginal utility of -1.5 claimed to be true by Maital for the United States is also assumed to be true for Thailand. This value is used to find the share of each income class in the total distribution of private good income, after which the total public good expenditures are allocated according to the pattern of the shares obtained. The results of this allocation and the new post-fisc income distribution using the A-M-M method are presented in Table H.1 below. It can be seen from Table H.1 that the resulting post-fisc income distribution based on the A-M—M method has become much more unequal than the same distribution based on Assumption III in this study, which is regarded here as the most de-equalizing assumption. The lowest income class in the distribution under the A-M-M approach shares only 2.9 percent of the total money income after the effects of government fiscal activities are taken into account, whereas under Assumption III and Assumption I of this study the same income class receives 3.7 percent and 4.9 percent of the total income, respectively. At the same time the highest income group, under the A-M-M assumption, always receives the highest income share. The Gini concentration ratios for the post-fisc income distri- bution are estimated at .6041, .5614, and .5289 under the A-M—M method, Assumption III, and Assumption I, respectively. 320 $3. 38. $8. ufiflammmoo go o.ooa o.oeH o.oeH m.mmv.mo e.mmm.HH m.mmo.em a.mma.me mmmmmHo Ham a.am m.mm a.am m.mem.mm m.mmm.m m.mee.om m.moa.m~ um>o new ooo.ma m.m m.m m.m o.~e~.e a.mwm o.m>m.m e.m~a.m mam.n~uooo.ma e.e o.m e.e m.eeo.m «.mev o.~em.v u.eom.m mem.eauooo.ma m.a m.m m.m m.mmm.m a.mom m.m¢~.m m.mo~.e mme.aaueeo.m e.ea v.oa e.a o.e¢m.m m.ma» o.mmm.m m.ame.v mmm.m ueoe.m m.m m.m m.e m.ame.m m.aem m.amm.v ~.Amm.m mmm.m loco.m m.v m.m m.m m.aflo.~ m.mma m.mmm.a m.~m~.H ooo.m gene: A a w zrzua H .udmma. HHH .ammma muammewm meooaH msooeH an v @006 eooo gem aoafiflbfle 83:3me 332a 393a 28888 888 889m 9605 omflhlumom 9.005 omwmuumonfi Beam no 8932 5 88:: 143m men. 5 8,5 805% one 693m: HSHmzumuHmUzlcng so @093 9505 m0 20343330 omflmlumom on» no Smwuazoolai 3an 321 This indicates that the A-M-M method, if used, would cause at least a 7.6 percent increase in income inequality in Thailand under the money income based in 1969 over the most de-equalizing assumption used in this study. The use of this A-M-M method would provide an ideal case in support of the contention that the government of Thailand has effected very little change in income distribu- tion. Indeed, instead of improving the present distribution, the public sector actually worsens it. However, the A-M-M method is not used as the main method here because it is believed to be inconsistent or incongruous with the approach adopted in this study regarding the allocation of public good benefits (which is to examine the disaggregated details of public good expenditures and then allocate the benefits to either general or specific beneficiaries according to the chosen objective or subjective criteria). Oddly enough, the present demonstration does not refute the main findings in this study; rather, it adds more weight to those findings, namely, that the Thai government is not merely indifferent to the issue of income redistribution, but is Opposed to it. lHenry Aaron and Martin McGuire, "Public Goods and Income Distribution," Econometrica,38 (November, 1920), pp. 907-20. 2 Ibid., p. 911. 3Shlomo Maital, "Public Goods and Income Distribution," Econometrica, 41 (May, 1973), pp. 561-68. ' SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY SELECTED BI BLIOGRAPHY Aaron, Henry and McGuire, Martin. "Public Goods and Income Distribution." Econometrica, 38 (November, 1970), pp. 907-920. Adelman, Irma and Morris, Cynthia T. "An Anatomy of Patterns of Income Distribution in Developing Nations." U.S. Department of State, Agency for International Develop- ment (AID), 1971, (Mimeographed). . Economic Growth and Social Equity in Developing Countries. Stanford: Stanford UniversIty Press, 1973. Adler, John H. "Development and Income Distribution." Weltwirtschaftliche Archiv, Bond 108, Heft 3 (1972), pp. 329-343. . "The Fiscal System, the Distribution of Income, and Public Welfare." In Kengon E. Poole, ed. Fiscal Policies and the American Economy. Prentice- Hall, 1951. Pp- 359-421. Ahluwalia, Montek S. "Income Inequality: Some Dimensions of the Problem." Finance and Development, 11 (September, 1974), pp. 2-9. Aitchison, J. and Brown, J. A. C. The Lognormal Distribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1957. Arrow, Kenneth J. Social Choice and Individual Values. 2nd ed. New York: Wiley, 1963.1 Atkinson, A. B. "On the Measurement of Inequality." Journal of Economic Theory, 2 (1970), pp. 244-263. ., ed. Wealth, Income, and Inequality. Hammonds- worth: Penguin Books, Inc., 1973. Ayal, Eliezer B. "Public Policies in Thailand under the Constitutional Regime: A Case Study of an Under- developed Country." Ph.D. Dissertation, Cornell University, 1962. Each, George, L. and Ardo, Albert. "The Redistributional Effects of Inflation." Review of Economics and Statistics, 39 (February, 1957), pp. 1-13. 322 323 Barna, Tibor. Redistribution of Incomes through Public Finance in 1937. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1945. Behrens, Jean and Smolensky, Eugene. "Alternative Defini- tions of Income Redistribution." Public Finance, 28 (1973). PP. 315-332. Bertrand, Trent J. "Rural Taxation in Thailand." Pacific Affairs, 42 (Summer, 1969), pp. 178-188. Bhagwati, Jagdish N., ed. Economics and World Order. London: MacMillan, 1972. Bird, Richard M. "Income Distribution and Tax Policy in Columbia." Economic Development and Cultural Change, 18 (1970): pp. 519-535. . Taxation and Development: Lessons from Columbian Experience. Cambridge: Harvard UnIVersIty Press, 1970. and DeWulf, Luc. "Taxation and Income Distribution in Latin America: A Critical Review of Empirical Studies." International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 23 (November, 1973), pp. 639-681. Bonnen, James T. "The Absence of Knowledge of Distribution Impacts: An Obstacle to Effective Public Program Analysis and Decisions." In U.S., Congress, Joint Economic Committee. The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969, pp. 419-449. . "The Distribution of Benefits from Cotton Price Supports." In Samuel B. Chase, Jr., ed. Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis. Washington, D. C.: Brookings Institution, 1968, pp. 223-254. Boulding, Kenneth E. and Pfaff, Martin, eds. Redistribution 39 the Rich and the Poor. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth, 1972. Breit, William. "Income Redistribution and Efficiency Norms.‘ In Harold M. Hochman and George E. Peterson, eds. Redistribution Through Public Choice. New York: Columbia University Press, 1974, pp. 3-21. Bronfenbrenner, Martin. "Equality and Equity." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973). PP. 9-23. 324 . Income Distribution Theory. Chicago: Aldine, 1971. Brownlee, O. H. and Conrad, Alfred. "Effects upon the Distribution of Income of a Tight Money Policy." American Economic Review, 51 (May, 1961), pp. 74-85. Cartter, Allan M. The Redistribution of Income in Postwar Britain: A Study of the Effects of the Central Government Fiscal Program in 1948-1949. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1955. Champernowne, D. G. "A Comparison of Measures of Inequality of Income Distribution." Economic Journal, 84 (December, 1974), pp. 787-816. Chenery, H.B. e: 31. Redistribution with Growth. London: Oxford University Press, published for the World Bank and the Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex, 1974. Clark, Colin and Struwel, Geer, eds. Income and Wealth, Series X, Income Redistribution and the Statistical Foundation of Economic Policy. New Haven: Interna- tional Association for Research in Income and Wealth, 1964. Cline, William R. "Distribution and Development." Journal of Development Economics, 1 (February, 1975), pp. 359—400. . Potential Effects of Income Redistribution on Economic Growth: Latin American Cases. New York: Praeger, 1972. Dalton, Hugh. Some Aspects of the Inequalitypof Incomes in Modern Communities. London: George Routledge and Sons, Ltd., 1920. Development Economics Department, Public and Private Finance Division, World Bank. "Distributive Impact of Public Expenditures: A Research Proposal." September, 1973 (Mimeographed). DeWulf, Luc. "Do Public Expenditures Reduce Inequality?" Finance and Development, 11 (September, 1974), pp. 20—23. . "Fiscal Incidence Studies in Developing Countries: Survey and Critique." International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 22 (March, 1975), pp. 61-131. 325 Dodge, David A. "Impact of Tax, Transfer, and Expenditure Policies of Government on the Distribution of Personal Income in Canada." The Review of Income and Wealth, 21 (March, 1975), pp. 1-52. Eckstein, Otto. Water Resource Development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1958. Edwards, Richard C.: Reich, Michael; and Weisskopf, Thomas E. The Capitalist System: A Radical Analysis of American Society. Englewood, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1972. Franzen, Thomas; Lougren, Kerstin: and Rosenberg, Irma. "Redistributional Effects of Taxes and Public Expen- ditures in Sweden." The Swedish Journal of Economics, 77 (1975), pp. 31-55. Friedman, Milton. Capital and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962. . "Choice, Chance, and the Personal Distribution of Income." Journal of Political Economy, 61 (August, 1953), PP. 277-290. Galbraith, John Kenneth. The New Industrial State. 2nd ed. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin, 1971. . "Power and the Useful Economist." American Economic Review, 63 (March, 1973), pp. 1-11. Gaswirth, Joseph L. "The Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Gini Index." Review of Economics and Statistics, 54 ( , 1972), PP. 306-316. Gillespie, W. Irwin. The Incidence of Taxes and Public Expenditures in the Canadian Economy. Studies of the Royal Commission on Taxation, Number 2. Ottawa: Queen's Printer, 1966. . "Effect of Public Expenditure on the Distribution of Income." In Richard A. Masgrave, ed. Essays in Fiscal Federalism. Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1965, pp. 122-186. Gordon, David M. "Taxation of the Poor and the Normative Theory of Tax Incidence." American Economic Review, 62 (May, 1972): pp. 319-328. Greene, Kenneth V. "Collective Decision-Making Models and the Measurement of Benefits in Fiscal Incidence Studies." National Tax Journal, 26 (June, 1973), pp. 177-185. 326 Haig, Robert M., ed. The Federal Income Tax. New York: Columbia University Press, 1921. Hansen, W. Lee and Weisbrod, Burton A. "Distributional Effects of Public Expenditure Programs." Public Finance, 27 (1972), pp. 414-420. . "Who Pays for a Public Expenditure Program?" National Tax Journal, 24 (December, 1971): pp. 515-517. Haq, Mahbub ul. "Employment in the 19705: A New Perspective." A Statement Prepared for the Society for International Development 12th World Conference, Geneva, 16-19 May, 1971 (Mimeographed). Harberger, Arnold C. "The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax." Journal of Political Economy, 70 (June, 1962), PP. 215-240. . "Fiscal Policy and Income Distribution." Paper prepared for the WorkshOp on Income Distribution in Less Developed Countries, Princeton University, June 12-13, 1974. Harcourt, George C. Some Cambridge Controversies in the Theory of Capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972. Hirschman, Albert 0. "The Changing Tolerance for Income Inequality in the Course of Economic Development." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (November, 1973), pp. 544-566. ' Hochman, Harold M. and Peterson, George E. Redistribution through Public Choice. New York: Columbia Univer- sity Press, 1974. Hunt, Shane. "Distribution, Growth, and Government Economic Behavior in Peru." In Gustav Ranis. ed. Government and Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971, pp. 374-416. Ingram, James C. Economic Change in Thailand, 1850-1970. 2nd ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1971. Johnson, Harry G. "Some Micro-Economic Reflections on Income and Wealth Inequalities." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 109 (September, 1973), pp. 53-60. Johnson, James A. The Incidence of Government Revenues and Expenditures. A Study Prepared for the Ontario Committee on Taxation. Frank Fogg, Queen's Printer, n.d. 327 Kuznets, Simon. "Economic Growth and Income Inequality." American Economic Review, 45 (March, 1955). PP- 1-28. . "Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: VIII, Distribution of Income by Size." Economic Development and Cultural Change, 11 (January, 1963), pp. 1-80. Lewchalermwong, Anan. Taxation and Tax Reform in Thailand. Bangkok: Kurusapha Ladprao Press, 1971. Lydall, H. The Structure of Earnings. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1968. McCleary, William A. "Sources of Change in Distribution of Income in Thailand, 1962/63 and 1968/69." Discussion Paper no. 26, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, Bangkok, 1972 (Mimeographed). McLure, Charles E., Jr. "The Incidence of Taxation in West Malaysia." The Malayan Economic Review, 17 (October, 1972), pp. 66-98. "The Distribution of Income and Tax Incidence in Panama, 1969." Discussion Paper no. 36. Program of Development Studies, Rice University, 1972 (Mimeographed). . "The Incidence of Colombian Taxes, 1970." Discussion Paper no. 41, Program of Development Studies, Rice University, Summer, 1973.(Mimeographed). . "On the Theory and Methodology of Estimating Benefit and Expenditure Incidence." Paper presented at the WorkshOp on Income Distribution and Its Role in Development, Rice University, April 26, 1974 (Mimeographed). Maital, Shlomo. "Public Goods and Income Distribution: Some Further Results." Econometrica, 41 (May, 1973), pp. 561-568. Mann, Arthur J. "The Income Redistributional Effects of the Peurto Rican Fiscal System." Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Florida, 1971. Mathew, T. "Shifting and Incidence of Corporate Income Tax: A Review." The Indian Economic Journal, 20 (October- December, 1972), pp. 257-274. 328 Kakwani, N. C. and Podder, N. "On the Estimation of Lorenz Curves from Grouped Observations." International Economic Review, 14 (June, 1973): pp. 278-291. . "Efficient Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Associated Inequality Measures from Grouped Observa- tions." World Bank Development Research Center Discussion Papers, no. 10, October, 1974 (Mimeographed). Kambhu, Xujati. "Water Resources DevelOpment in Thailand and Its Policy." Ministry of National Development, Bangkok, December 27, 1963 (Mimeoqraphed). Karageorgas, D. "The Distribution of Tax Burden by Income Groups in Greece." Economic Journal, 73 (June, 1973), pp. 436-448. Kerdphibul, Udom. "Income and the Distribution of Income of the Agricultural Sector." Thai Journal of Agricul- tural Economics, 11 (December, 1972), pp. 1-24. Klein, Lawrence R. An Introduction to Econometrics. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1962. Kravis, Irving B. "International Differences in the Distri- bution of Income." Review of Economics and Statistics, 42 (November, 1960), pp. 408-416. . "A World of Unequal Incomes." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 409 (September, 1973), pp. 61-80. Krongkaew, Medhi and Chernsiri, Chintana. "The Measurement of the Poverty Level in Thailand." Thammasat University Journal, 5 (June-September, 1975). Krutilla, John V. and Eckstein, Otto. Multiple Purpose River Development: Studies in Applied Economic Analysis. Baltimore: Resources for the Future, Inc., 1958. ' Krzyzaniak, Marian, ed. Effects of the Corporate Income Tax. Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1966. and Musgrave, Richard A} The Shifting of the Corporate Income Tax. Baltimore: John HOpkins, 1963. and Ozmucur, Sfileyman. "The Distribution of Income and the Short-run Burden of Taxes in Turkey, 1968." Finanzarchiv, 32 (1973), pp. 69—97. 329 Meerman, Jacob P. "Fiscal Incidence in Empirical Studies of Income Distribution in Poor Countries." Department of State, Agency for International Development Discussion Paper no. 25, December, 1972 (Mimeographed). Meesook, Oey Astra. "Income Distribution Statistics for Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia." Paper prepared for the workshop on Income Distribution in Less Developed Countries, Princeton University, June 12-13, 1974. . "The Impact of Price Increases on Different Income Groups." Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, August, 1975 (Mimeographed). . Income Distribution in Thailand. Bangkok: Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, 1975. Mieszkowski, Peter. "Tax Incidence Theory: The Effects of Taxes on the Distribution of Income." The Journal of Economic Literature, 7 (December, 1969), pp. 1103- 1124. Miliband, Ralph. The State in Capitalist Sociepy. London: Wiedenfeld and Nicholson, 1969. Musgrave, Richard A. The Theory of Public Finance. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1959. . "Estimating the Distribution of the Tax Burden." In Problems of Tax Administration in Latin America. Papers and proceedings in a conference held in Buesnos Aires, Argentina, October, 1961. Baltimore: John Hopkins, 1965. ., ed. Essays on Fiscal Federalism. Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1965. .; Carrol, J. J.: Cook, L. D.; and Frame, L. "Distribution of Tax Payments by Income Class: A Case Study for 1948." National Tax Journal, 1 (March, 1951). PP. 1-48. ., and Daicoff, Darwin, W. "Who Pays Michigan Taxes?" Michigan Tax Study Staff Papers, (1958), pp. 131-182. ., and Musgrave, Peggy B. Public Finance in Theory and Practice. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1973. Nell, Edward J. "The Fall of the House of Efficiency." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Soc1a1 Science, 409 (September, 1973): PP. 102-111. 330 O'Connor, James. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1973. Oshima, Harry T. "The International Comparison of Size Distribution of Family Incomes with Special Reference to Asia." Review of Economics and Statistics, 44 (November, 1962), pp. 439-445. . "Income Inequality and Economic Growth: The Postwar Experience of Asian Countries." The Malayan Economic Review, 15 (October, 1970), PP. 7-41. Paukert, Felix. "Income Distribution at Different Levels of Development: A Survey of Evidence." International Labour Review, 108 (August-September, 1973), pp. 97- 125. Peacock, A. T., ed. Income Redistribution and Social Polipy: A Set of Studies. London: Cape, 1954. Pechman, Joseph A. "The Distributional Effects of Public Higher Education in California." Journal of Human Resources, 5 (Summer, 1970), pp. 361-370. ., and Okner, Benjamin A. Who Bears the Tax Burden? Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1974. Pen, Jan. Income Distribution: Facts, Theories, and Policies. New York: Praeger, 1971. Phelps, Edmond 8., ed. Economic Justice: Selected Readings. Harmondsworth, Middlesex: Penguin Books, Inc., 1973. Poole, Kenyon E., ed. Fiscal Policies and the American Economy. New York: Prentice-Hall, 1951. Prest, Alan R. "Statistical Calculations of Tax Burdens." Economica, 87 (August, 1955), pp. 234-245. . "The Budget and Interpersonal Distribution." Public Finance, 23 (1968). PP. 80-98. Quandt, Richard E. "Old and New Methods of Estimating the Pareto Distribution." Metrika, 10 (1966), pp. 55-82. Rawls, John. A Theory of Justice. Combridge: Harvard University Press, 1971. Recktenwald, Horst-Claus. Tax Incidence and Income Redistribution: An Introduction. Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1971. 331 Reynolds, Morgan and Smolensky, Eugene. "The Post Fisc Distribution: 1961 and 1970 Compared." National Tax Journal, 27 (December, 1974), PP. 515-530. Riggs, Fred W. Thailand: The Modernization of a Bureaucratic Polity. Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1966. Sahota, Gian S. "Public Expenditures and Income Distribution in Panama." USAID, Panama City, August, 1972 (Mimeographed). Sakuntalaksna, Prachark. "An Economic Analysis of the Thai Direct Tax System: Evaluation and Suggestions for Reform." M. A. Thesis, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, 1972. Salkin, Jay S. "On the Direct Measurement of Tax Progressivity in Thailand." National Tax Journal, 27 (June, 1974), PP. 301-318. and Chalayonvatn, Darunee. "Changes in Tax Incidence in Thailand from 1963 to 1968." Discussion Paper no. 39, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, March 20, 1974 (Mimeographed). Samudavanija, Chai Anan. "The Politics and Administration of the Thai Budgetary Process." Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin, 1971. Samuelson, Paul A. "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure." Review of Economics and Statistics, 36 (November, 1954): pp. 387-389. . "Diagrammatic Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure." Review of Economics and Statistics, 37 (November, 1955) Sanguanruang, Saeng. "Net Resource Flow Between Agriculture and Non-Agriculture in Thailand in 1953 and 1963." Ph.D. Dissertation, Indiana University, 1971. Sanittanont, Sura. Thailand's Rice Equrt Tax: Its Effects on the Rice Economy. Bangkok: National Institute of Development Administration, 1967. Sawyers, Larry and Wachtel, Howard M. "Theory of the State, Government Tax and Purchasing Policy, and Income Distribution." The Review of Income and Wealth, 21 (March, 1975), pp. 111-124. Sen, Amartya. On Economic Inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1973. 332 Shoup, Carl 8. Public Finance. Chicago: Aldine, 1969. Siamwala, Ammar. "Rice." Thammasat University Journal, 3 (May, 1974), pp. 5-91. Siffin, William J. The Thai Bureaucracy: Institutional Change and Development. Honolulu: East-West Center Press, 1966. Simons, Henry C. Personal Income Taxation: The Definition of Income as a Problem of Fiscal Poligy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1938. Singer, Neil M. "Income Redistribution through the Federal Budget in 1959." Ph.D. Dissertation, Stanford University, 1965. Small, Leslie E. "Water Control and Development in the Central Plain of Thailand." Southeast Asia, 3 (Spring, 1974), pp. 679-697. Snodgrass, Donald R. "The Fiscal System as an Income Redistributor in West Malaysia." Public Finance, 29 (1974), PP. 56-76. Stark, Thomas. The Distribution of Personal Income in the U. K., 1949-1963. Combridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972. Tan, Edita A. "Taxation, Government Spending, and Income Distribution in the Philippines." Paper prepared for the Joint JERC-CAMS Seminar on Income Distribution, Employment, and Economic Development in Southeast and East Asia, Tokyo, December 16-20, 1974. Tawney, Ralph H. Equalipy. London: Urwin Books, 1964. Tax Foundation, Inc. Tax Burdens and Benefits of Government Expenditures by Income Class, 1961 and 1965. New York: Tax Foundation, 1967. Taylor, Milton C. and others. Fiscal Survey of Colombia. A Report Prepared under the Direction of the Joint Tax Program of the OrganiZation of American States and the Inter-American Development Bank. Baltimore: John HOpkins, 1965. Thailand. Budget Bureau. 'Annual Budget. 1963, 1965, 1969 and 1971. Va We Wei 333 . Government Revenue. 1963 and 1969. . Records of Government Activities, 1969. Thailand. Department of Comptroller General. Report of Receipts and Outlays of the Kingdom of Thailand, 1963 and 1969. Thailand. National Economic and Development Board. National Income of Thailand, 1968-1969 edition, and 1972-1973 edition. - Thailand. National Statistical Office. Reports of the Household Expenditures Survey, 1962-1963, 7 volumes. . Report of the Socio-Economic Survey, 1968-1969. Report of the Population and Housing Census, 1970. . Statistical Yearbook of Thailand, no. 28, (1968-1969) and no. 29 (1970-1971). United Nations.» Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East. Economic Survey of Asia and the Far East, 1971. Bangkok, I972. . International Trade Projections, Effective Protec- tion and Income Distribution, Vol. III: Income Dis- tribution. Bangkok, 1972. Van Roy, Edward. "The Persuit of Growth and Stability through Taxation of Agricultural Exports: Thailand's Ex- perience." Public Finance, 23 (1968), pp. 294-317. Webb, Richard C. "The Distribution of Income in Peru." Discussion Paper no. 26, Research Proqram in Economic Development, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton Univer- sity, September, 1972 (Mimeographed). . "Tax Policy and the Incidence of Taxation in Peru." Discussion Paper no. 27, Research Program in Economic Development, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University, September, 1972 (Mimeographed). Weisbrod, Burton A. "Income Redistribution Effects and Benefit-Cost Analysis." In Samuel B. Chase, Jr;, ed. Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis. Washington, D. C.: The Brookings Institution, 1968, pp. 177-222. , and Hansen, W. Lee. Benefits, Costs, and Finance of Public Higher Education. Chicago: Markham, 1969. 334 Weisskoff, Richard. "Income Distribution and Economic Growth in Puerto Rico, Argentina, and Mexico." Review of Income and Wealth, 16 (December, 1970), pp. 303-332. Weisskopf, Thomas E. "Capitalism, Underdevelopment, and the Future of the Poor Countries." In Jagdish Bhagwati, ed., Economics and World Order. New York: Mac- Millan, 1972, pp. 1-49.