I “AM" ‘ ' ‘ I .. I ' " " _ l I. ’ ' - I . I 'J'lw I v v I?“ J 3? -“ ”VQ?J ‘ 1“ I I," ." - "1;..5' :lLIE- 0 II II ' H'. '9" VIII-'1}; "I -| IIIilI WWI. I . 315a: Vl‘ [3ng IL, I; -x_ s? I ‘- ‘ ‘ - ‘ .- .. K: . _ :;_§°v \_ ,: , - ,'_ . _ :Cl ‘F ' g _ . _— I:' ' " ' * ' u - ~ ._ _ y" 2‘1 NEAT}; ”I" 'F': lil':::I-' 1:".3“ ., : ,w;.« ;-,-- :rc , f‘ fi’ ”'“I’ r;i‘.":i.;il' ""‘Vt'j:If ‘1 1 ",' {.1 WM. '2’ . ‘ I‘ ; w Iii 1.. ALI 'II 1'. 2': ltg‘IILI-I‘ if . j” ' ‘ “I . LIT KY Nlitli'mn State 1 University r 11—. —---—- -‘-1' This is to certify that the thesis entitled Strategies for Increasing Food Production and Income on Smali Upland Farms in Lampung, Indonesia -- A Linear Programming Analysis presented by Uben Parhusip has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Agrig. EQQII. M %JM Major professor Date June 13, 1980 07639 OVERDUE FINES: 25¢ per day per item RETURNING LIBRARY MATERIALS: Place in book return to rem0ve ‘~‘\\":| charge from circulation records STRATEGIES FOR INCREASING FOOD PRODUCTION AND INCOME ON SMALL UPLAND FARMS IN LAMPUNG, INDONESIA--A LINEAR PROGRAMMING ANALYSIS BY Uben Parhusip A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1980 C§//éw7¢) ABSTRACT STRATEGIES FOR INCREASING FOOD PRODUCTION AND INCOME ON SMALL UPLAND FARMS IN LAMPUNG, INDONESIA--A LINEAR PROGRAMMING ANALYSIS BY Uben Parhusip The major purpose of this study was to analyze empirically the effects of the adoption of the new tech- nology on the traditional cropping system on the small upland farms in the transmigration areas of Lampung, Indo- nesia. The analysis emphasized the changes in key farm variables of farm income, crop enterprise combinations, resource use and productivity. Also estimates were made of the price elasticities of the normative supply functions of the major food crops of rice, corn, and cassava. The survey method was used to collect empirical data from a number of sample farms in the transmigration areas of Lampung where upland farming for food crOp pro- duction is the main agricultural activity. For the selec- tion of the sample farms a two stage sampling method was used. The first stage identified four villages to repre- sent Lampung province. The second stage involved random sampling of farms in each village. Tatakarya Village, Adiluih and Bulusari Villages, and Pugung Raharja Village Uben Parhusip were selected to represent the North, Central, and South of Lampung respectively. A static linear programming model, designed to maxi- mize the gross margin subject to meeting minimum food crop consumption requirements of the farming household, was the computational tool in this farm planning analysis. Variable price programming was used to generate data for normative supply functions of the three major food crops. Then regres- sion analysis was used to estimate the price elasticities of the normative supply of these major food crops. The study suggests that in 1979 only one of the three regions has much possibility to increase food pro- duction and farm income. This is in North Lampung. The results of the analysis show that there is little potential to increase farm income and food production through the adoption of currently available new technology for the representative farms in Central and South Lampung. Most of the currently available new technology apparently has been adopted. In North Lampung some potential appears to remain for further adoption of currently available new technology, in this relatively newly settled transmigration area. For Central and South Lampung the major efforts to increase food production and farm income could be the devel- Opment of research to produce new highly profitable inputs or import them from the other areas with testing at the farm level. Examples of such new inputs include new seeds, fertilizers, insecticides, new cultural practices, and Uben Parhusip mixed cropping for the small farmers. Also needed is the training of the farmers for the use of these new inputs, and farmers' organizations for the distribution of these new inputs and for marketing the products. The efforts such as of Tani Makmur Project in this regard need to be con- tinued and expanded. The analysis also shows that there is a compara- tive advantage in producing specific crops with specific cropping patterns in each region. North Lampung has a com- parative advantage in producing cassava and upland rice with the cropping pattern: corn + upland rice { cassava. Central Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing rice and cassava with cropping patterns consisting of crop mixtures: corn - soybeans + cassava, and corn + upland rice f cassava. South Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing soy- beans with cropping patterns: upland rice - soybeans, upland rice + corn - soybeans, and triple crops of soybeans. Labor is particularly limiting during land prepara- tion and weeding seasons in North Lampung. The increase in the availability of labor in these peak seasons could signi- ficantly increase farm income and output. Hired labor is very small during these peak seasons which may be due to the absence of landless farmers in the study area. In general operating capital was not a limiting factor for the repre- sentative farmers, most of whom practiced mixed cropping. But medium to long term credit may be needed for investment in the additional sources of power (e.g., cows and other Uben Parhusip sources of power) to reduce the labor constraints in the peak seasons. The products of the variable price programming anal- ysis were the step normative supply functions for rice, corn, and cassava under traditional and new technologies. These step supply functions were then transformed into the continuous supply functions by means of regression analysis. From these continuous supply functions then, price elas- ticities were calculated for these three major food crops. For specific use for policy makers these elasticity coef- ficients were converted into absolute changes in output response to a 1 percent change in prices. All the supply functions of the three major crops were inelastic in the price range from existing levels to somewhat higher levels. Under the new technology the sup- ply curves of the three crops shift upward to the right indicating that the new technology would increase produc- tion of rice, corn, and cassava at all price levels in the study area. The price elasticities for cassava and corn are higher under the new technology than under the traditional technology. In all cases the price elasticity of cassava is the highest and price increases for cassava are the most effective means to increase both cassava production and farm income compared with the other two cr0ps. Dedicated to my parents Saul br. Lumbanraja and Jabidu Parhusip for all sacrifices they have made for my education in Indonesia and the United States ii AC KNOWLED GMENTS The author wishes to thank Professor John N. Ferris, chairman of both my guidance and thesis committees. To him I am indebted for his guidance and encouragement during the preparation of this dissertation. Thanks to Professors Stephen Harsh, Robert D. Stevens, and Carl Liedholm, for their contributions and assistance. I benefitted a great deal from Robert D. Stevens' comments on the earlier draft of this dissertation. Much appreciation is extended to Dr. Clive Gray in the earlier preparation of my study program during his stay in Indonesia; the United States Agency for International Development for financial support through my graduate studies; Ir. Sardjono Reksodimulyo, Director of Program Development for Food Crops; Ir. Achmad Affandi, Director General of Food Crops in the Ministry of Agriculture in Jakarta for giving me a chance to study on leave; the Ford Foundation Jakarta for supporting my family and partly fund- ing my research project; Professor Yoshi Tsurumi, Director of the Pacific Basin Business and Economic Study Center, Graduate School of Management, University of California (UCLA) Los Angeles, California, who has provided major iii funding for my research project in Lampung, Indonesia; Ir. Kusnadi Affandi, Inspector of Lampung Agricultural Exten— sion Agency and his staff members, Ir. M. Pohan, Ir. Kamaluddin Sipayung for their help; Ir. Masdulhaq, Ir. Saibun Sirait, Ir. Djamaan, Ir. Sulaeman Nasution of the Lampung Extension Specialists for providing their help in collecting the data; the farmers in Tatakarya, Bulusari, Adiluih, and Pugung Raharja Villages in Lampung for their invaluable cooperation and patience in providing information upon which this study relied; Chris Wolf and Ing Ting for their assistance in computer work. A sincere debt of gratitude is owed to my brother and his wife, my sister and her husband who have sacrificed a lot in all ways to see that I made it this far. Last, but not least to my wife Purnama, my daughters Lola, Betty, Nimbella, and my son Bernard (Ucok) for their patience, understanding, and encouragement during the preparation of this dissertation. Finally, I am grateful to God for guiding me and my family and keeping us alive. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS Page LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix LIST OF FIGURES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiv Chapter I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . l 1.1 The Problem and Its Setting . . . . . 1 1.2 Theory of Agricultural Development. . . 8 1.3 The Research Approach . . . . . o H U1 1.3.1 The Analytical Framework. . . . 17 1.3.2 Some Advantages and Limitations of Linear Programming Approach . 20 1.3.3 Sources of Data. . . . 21 1.3.4 Sampling Method and the Sample Size. . . . . . . . . . 22 1.3.5 Data Collection. . . . . . . 26 1.3.6 Construction of the Representa- tive Farms. . . . . . . . 27 1.4 Organization of the Study. . . . . . 30 II. DESCRIPTION OF THE FARMING SYSTEM IN THE STUDY AREA 0 C O O O O O O O O O O 3 1 2.1 Physical Characteristics of the Study Area 0 O O O O O O O I O O O 31 2.1.1 Soil and Climate of the Research Area. . . . . . . . . . 32 Land Use . . . . . . . . . . . 34 Cr0p Production and CrOpping Patterns. . 35 Technology of Agricultural Production. . 39 Some Demographic Characteristics of the Representative Family Farms in the Study Area . . . . . . . . . 41 2.6 Educational Level of Representative Farm Household's Head . . . . . . 44 NNNN O O I O 01wa Chapter 2.7 2.8 Farm Labor Force . . . . . . . . Farm Capital . . . . . . . . . III. THE STRUCTURE OF THE LINEAR PROGRAMMING MODELS FOR THE STUDY AREA 0 O C O O O O C O 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.5 Introduction . . . . . . . . . The Objective Function . . . . . . Activities in the Model. . . . . . a. Crop Production Activities . . . b. Labor and Animal Hiring Activities. c. Capital Borrowing Activities. . . d. Fertilizers, Insecticides, and Food Buying Activities. . . . e. Food Crop Consumption Activities . f. Crops Selling Activities and Seed Production Activities . . . . 9. Transfer Activities. . . . . . Restrictions in the Model . . . . . a. Land Restriction. . . . . . . b. Labor Restrictions . . . . . c. Operating Capital Restrictions . . d. Consumption Requirements . . . . Some Limitations of the Model. . . . IV. ANALYSIS OF THE RESULTS FROM THE LINEAR PROGRAMMING MODELS APPLICATIONS. . . . . 4.1 The Optimal Organization of the Repre- sentative Farm Enterprise Under Traditional with Existing Resource Conditions in North Lampung. . . The Effects of the New Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung . Comparison of Optimal Plan Under the New Technology and Existing Resource Levels Between the Three Subregions of Lampung . . . . . . . The Effects of Releasing Family Labor Constraints on the Optimal Plan Under the New Technology. . . . . . . vi Page 44 54 59 59 62 65 65 70 74 76 76 78 79 79 79 80 81 82 82 84 86 96 111 115 Chapter 4.5 Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farms Under the New Technology with Existing _Resources . . . . . . . . . . 4.6 Summary of the Results from Linear Programming Analysis . . . . . . V. NORMATIVE SUPPLY FUNCTIONS FOR MAJOR FOOD CROPS UNDER TRADITIONAL AND NEW TECHNOLOGIES. 5.1 Introduction. . . . . . . . . 5.2 Normative Supply Function of Rice, Corn, and Cassava . . . . . . . 5.2.1 Rice Supply Functions . . . . 5.2.2 Corn or Maize Supply Functions . 5.2.3 Cassava Supply Functions . . . 5.3 The Effects of the New Technology on Price Elasticities of the Supply of the Major Food Crops . . . . . . VI. SUMMARY, POLICY IMPLICATIONS, LIMITATIONS OF THE STUDY AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH O O O O O O C O O O O O O 6.1 smary O O O O O O O O O O O 6.2 Policy Implications . . . . . . 6. 3 Limitations and Suggestion for Further Study 0 O O O O O O O O O O APPENDICES Appendix A. Maps of Indonesia and Lampung Province . . . B. Major Food Crop Production by Subregions of Laxnpung O O O O O O O O O O O O O C. Explanation of the Abbreviations Used in Cr0pping Patterns of the Representative Farms in Lampung . . . . . . . . . . D. Explanation of Abbreviations Used in the Linear Programming Table of the Representative Farms in Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Page 124 132 135 135 144 144 149 154 158 175 175 184 187 191 193 197 200 Chapter Page E. Monthly Major Food CrOps Prices at the Nearest Market to the Representative Farms in Lampung O O O O I O O O O I O O O 2 0 8 BIBLIOGRAPHY .' . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210 viii Table 2.7 LIST OF TABLES Daily Wage Rates and Total Labor Inputs by Month on the Representative Family Farms (Bulusari Village) o .2 o o o o o o o o o o 0 Daily Wage Rates and Total Labor Inputs by Month in Lampung on the Representative Family Farms (Pugung Raharja Village) in Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . . Monthly Labor Inputs and Daily Wage Rates on the Representative Farms (Tatakarya Village) in Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . ix Page Areas and Population of Indonesia by Province for 1976 O O O O 0 O O O O O O O 3 Acreage Expansion of Lowland and Upland in Lampung for the Period of 1969-1976 . . . 7 Number and Percentage of Farmers by Cropping Patterns of the Representative Farms in Lampung I O O O O O O I O O O O 36 Average Area Devoted to Each Crapping Pattern by the Representative Farms in Lampung . . 38 Some Demographic Characteristics of the Repre- sentative Farm Households in Lampung. . . 42 Average Representative Farm Household's Head Educational Level . . . . . . . . . 43 Representative Farm Family Composition by Age Groups in Lampung . . . . . . . . . 46 Total Labor Inputs by Month and Wage Rates on the Representative Farms (Adiluih Village) in Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . 47 48 49 50 2.12 3.1 3.2 4.3 4.4 Page Man Equivalents Used in the RERU Farm Manage- ment Studies . . . . . . . . . . . 54 Table of Conversion of Various Working Age and Different Sex for Settlement Areas. . . . 55 Cash Expenses by the Representative Farms by Month in Lampung. . . . . . . . . . 58 CrOp Production Activities in Tatakarya Village (North Lampung) . . . . . . . . . . 66 Labor Requirement per Hectare of Selected Cr0p Production Activities Under Traditional and New Technologies. . . . . . . . . . 70 Hiring Labor and Animal Activities in Tatakarya Village . . . . . . . . . 72 Borrowing and Transfer Activities in Tatakarya Village. 0 O O O O O O C C O O O 75 Fertilizers, Food Crop Buying, Food Cr0p Con- sumption and Selling Activities in Tatakarya Village. 0 O O O O O O O O O O C 75 Optimal Plan, Gross Margin, Resource Use and Average Returns Under Traditional Technology and New Technology with Existing Resources of the Representative Farm in North Lampung, Indonesia . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 Marginal Value Products of Land, Family Labor, Operating Capital (MVPs) on the Optimal Plan Under Traditional Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung . . . . . . 92 A Comparison of the Optimum Farm Organization of the Representative Farm Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . 97 Cost of Forcing in NonOptimal Activities (Results of the Linear Programming Analysis) Under the New Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . . 100 Table Page 4.5 A Comparison of Marginal Value Products (MVPs) of Land, Family Labor, and Operating Capital on the Optimal Plan Under the Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources of the Representative Farm in North Lampung . 103 4.6 Optimum Organization of the Representative Farm Under the New Technology with Existing Resource Levels in Central Lampung . . . . 107 4.7 Optimum Organization of the Representative Farm After the Introduction of the New Tech- nology with Existing Resource Levels in South Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . 108 4.8 Comparison of the Level of Technology on Optimal Plans for the Representative Farms in the Three Subregions of Lampung . . . . 110 4.9 Comparison of the CrOpping Patterns of the Optimal Plans Under the New Technology and Existing Resources for the Representative Farms of the Three Subregions of Lampung . . 112 4.10 Comparison of Resource Use and Productivity on the Optimum Plans Under the New Technology with Existing Resources of the Representative Farms in the Three Subregions of Lampung . . 114 4.11 Comparison of CrOp Productivities in Various CrOpping Patterns Under the New Technology Between the Three Subregions of Lampung . . 116 4.12 Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Existing Resource Levels and Increased Family Labor in North Lampung . 118 4.13 Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Increased Family Labor in Central Lampung . . . . . . . . . 121 4.14 Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Increased Family Labor in South Lampung . . . . . . . . . . 123 4.15 A Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in North Lampung. . 125 xi Table 4.16 4.17 5.5 5.6 5.7 A Page Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in Central Lampung . 128 Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in South Lampung. . 130 Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Rice Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources of the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . . . . 146 Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Rice Price Varied on the Representative Farm in North Lampung . 148 Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Corn Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources and Labor Increased for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Corn Price Varied for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153 Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Cassava Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resource and Labor Increased for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . 155 Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Cassava Price Varied for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157 Estimated Supply Functions for Rice Under Tra- ditional and New Technologies for the Repre- sentative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . 161 Estimated Supply Functions for Corn Under Tra- ditional and New Technologies for the Repre- sentative Farm in North Lampung . . . . . 162 xii Table 5.9 5.10 5.11 5.13 Estimated Supply Functions for Cassava Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . Estimated Price Elasticities of Rice Supply Functions Under Traditional and New Tech— nologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . . Estimated Price Elasticities of Corn Supply Functions Under Traditional and New Techno- logies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . . . . Estimated Price Elasticities of Cassava Supply Functions Under Traditional and New Tech- nologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . . Absolute Increases in Production of Rice in Response to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative in North Lampung . . . Absolute Increases in Corn Production in Response to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. . Absolute Increases in Cassava Production in Response to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii Page 163 165 167 169 171 172 173 LI ST OF FIGURES Figure Page 2.1 Monthly Rainfall Pattern in Bandarjaya, Central Lampung, Indonesia, 1970-76 . . . . . . 33 5.1 Farm-Firm Step Supply Function. . . . . . 142 5.2 Normative Supply Functions for Rice Under Tra- ditional and New Technologies for the Repre- sentative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . 147 5.3 Normative Supply Functions for Corn Under Tra- ditional and New Technologies of the Repre- sentative Farm in North Lampung. . . . . 152 5.4 Normative Supply Functions for Cassava Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung . . . 156 xiv CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION 1.1 The Problem and Its Setting Indonesia has an area of about 2,027,000 square kilometers covering about 13,000 islands, of which about 2,000 are inhabited. The major islands are Sumatra, Java, Sulawesi, Kalimantan and Irian Jaya. Lampung is located in the south part of Sumatra. See map in Appendix A. For the purpose of agricultural statistics, the country is divided into (a) Java and Madura and (b) Outer Java Islands (FAO/UNDP, 1976). Indonesia to a great extent relies on the agricultural sector. For 1978 the agricultural sector's contribution to the Gross Domestic Product accounted for 31.1 percent compared with 17.8 percent for mining, manu- facturing 9.3 percent, trade and financial intermediaries and other services 31.4 percent (Central Bureau of Statis— tics, Indonesia, 1979). It is also estimated that about 75 percent of the total population is directly dependent on the agricultural sector for their livelihood. About 61.5 percent of the total labor force engages in agricul- tural activities. This sector is expected to supply food, raw materials, labor, and capital to the other sectors of the economy. The performance of agricultural sector has not kept pace with the growing population of Indonesia, even though the program for increasing food production, especially rice was initiated a long time ago. For example, in 1977/78 Indonesia imported about 3.3 million tons of food grain consisting of 2.3 million tons of rice and 1.0 million tons of wheat (Glassburner, 1978; World Bank, 1979). Even assum- ing an expanded government investment in the food crop sub- sector, improved technology, efficiently operating services and marketing management, and a growth rate of production at an average 3.5 percent per annum, with demand increasing at a rate of 5.0 percent per annum (Timmer, 1974; Parhusip, 1976), it is likely that Indonesia will continue to face a basic food deficit, i.e., rice. It is projected that the rice deficit could be between 2.0 and 3.0 million tons in 1990 (World Bank, 1979). The problem of increasing food production in Indo- nesia is also aggravated by the concentration of population on the island of Java. Table 1.1 shows the detail of popu- lation distribution by provinces. As can be seen from the table, for 1976, the population of Indonesia consisted of 130.7 million people of which 82 million people or 65.3 percent live in Java, an island with only 7 percent of the total area of Indonesia. Table 1.1.--Areas and Population of Indonesia by Province for 1976. Total Area . 12:53:22,121? Sq. Km. Percent 1. D.K.I. Jakarta 590 0.03 4925 2. West Java 46300 2.43 23849 3. Central Java 34206 1.80 23675 4. D.I. Jogyakarta 3169 0.17 2637 5. East Java 47922 2.52 27079 JAVA & MADURA 132187 6.95 82166 6. D.I. Aceh 55932 2.91 2299 7. N. Sumatra 70787 3.72 7347 8. W. Sumatra 49778 2.61 3077 9. Riau 94652 4.96 3070 10. Jambi 44924 2.36 1746 11. S. Sumatra 103688 5.44 3847 12. Bengkulu 21168 1.11 625 13. Lampung 33307 1.75 3452 SUMATRA 473606 24.86 22480 14. W. Kalimantan 146760 7.70 2136 15. C. Kalimantan 152600 8.01 834 16. S. Kalimantan 37660 1.98 1872 17. E. Kalimantan 202440 10.63 929 KALIMANTAN 539460 28.32 5773 18. N. Sulawesi 19023 1.00 1931 19. C. Sulawesi 69726 3.66 1047 20. S. Sulawesi 72781 3.82 5729 21. SE. Sulawesi 27686 1.45 798 SULAWESI 189216 9.93 9057 Table 1.1.--Continued. Total Area . Population PrOV1nce Sq. Km. Percent (thousand) 22. Bali 5561 _ 0.30 2333 23. W. Nusatenggara 20177 1.06 2474 24. E. Nusatenggara 47876 2.51 2496 25. Maluku 74505 3.91 1309 26. Irian Jaya 421981 22.16 1042 INDONESIA 1904569 100.00 130766 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics, Jakarta, Indonesia. Lampung province, the south part of Sumatra island has a population of 3.5 million people or 2.5 percent of the total population of Indonesia. Of the land area culti- vated in Java (46.7 percent of the total area) more than 70 percent of the farms had less than one hectare. The average family size on all farms was five. The land area cultivated in Lampung is only about 24.7 percent of the total area (Central Bureau of Statistics, 1979). On the outer islands there are vast areas of land potentially available for increasing food production. In Lampung itself there are 2.0 million hectares of such land (Bogor Soil Research Institute, 1971). The problem of population distribution has been partly tackled by the transmigration program from Java to outer islands. Thus these programs have the dual strate- gies of easing Java's population pressure and also develop- ing the outer islands. The intended impact is to increase food production, increase income per capita, create employ— ment opportunities and create new economic growth centers outside Java which are intended to attract new migrants. Lampung province has great potential both for increasing food production and as a transmigration program recipient. Lampung has been the major recipient of the transmigration in terms of the number of families for the period of 1969/70 through 1974/75. This is primarily due to its strategic location which is very close to Java, only one half hour by air or two hours by bus plus four hours by ferry. It also has relatively good transportation and communication facilities compared to the other regions of the outer islands. Another significant constraint on the development of agriculture is the low level of farm investment. The result is that land and labor continue to be the main inputs in food production, especially for upland crops in Lampung. The use of purchased inputs such as fertilizers and pesticides/insecticides are extremely low, especially in upland farming. The tools used in farming are mostly hoes and ploughs. The low level of production technology has been cited as one of the causes of poor performance of agricultural sector. Low productivity in Lampung province can be also attributed to the lack of the price incentive, insufficient resource base including lack of capital or credit, managerial know-how, shortage of labor and low land fertility. In Lampung the increase in food production is mostly due to increases in areas of lowland and upland cultivated. The following table shows the area expansion of upland and lowland for food crop production during the period of 1969- 1976. From the table we can see that, during that period, the total acreage increase was 30,000 ha and 90,000 ha or the rate of 5.6 percent and 7.5 percent per annum for low- land and upland respectively. In terms of acreage, upland contributed about 72 percent of the total area cultivated for food production. Table l.2.--Acreage Expansion of Lowland and Upland in Lampung for the Period of 1969-1976. Annual Change Annual Change “81:?“ ”3.1.2? ha % ha % 1969 65,793 - — 150,000 - - 1970 71,282 5,489 8.34 168,188 18,188 12.13 1971 77,836 6,554 9.19 198,877 30,689 18.25 1972 83,431 5,595 7.19 220,955 22,070 11.10 1973 90,791 7.360 8.82 227,014 6,059 2.74 1974 89,843 -3,703 -4.08 233,044 6,030 2.66 1975 89,843 2,755 3.16 227,103 -5,941 —2.55 1976 95,792 5,949 6.62 240,900 13,797 6.08 Average Annual 4,300 5.5 12,965 5.5 Change Source: Dinas Pertanian Rakyat Lampung: Repelita III Subsector Pertanian Tanaman Pangan Propinsi Lampung 1979/80- 1983/84. This is due to the well distributed rainfall during the year, and a very short dry season which is suitable for a year around upland cropping system (Kongres Agronomi, Jakarta, 1977). 1.2 Theory of Agricultural Development A background framework of theory of agricultural development will help place the results of this study in perspective. Schultz (1964) viewed that peasants, in tra- ditional agricultural systems, were rational, efficient resource allocators. They remain poor, because they had limited technical and economic opportunities to which they could respond. In this theory the agricultural transforma- tion requires investment in producing and introducing the new higher productivity agricultural inputs, such as high yielding seed varieties, and chemical fertilizers. This theory is incomplete since it treats technical change as exogenous to the economic system. Ruttan and Hayami (1971) augment agricultural development theory with an "Induced Development Model" which treats technical change as endo- genous to the development process in which both the private and public sectors are responsive to the relative price of factors. For example the mechanical technology is induced to be developed where there is labor scarcity (high cost labor) and biological technology is induced to be developed where land is a scarce resource (has high cost). Competitive conditions are assumed with profit maximizing behavior by farmers. To achieve a sizeable increase in agricultural pro- duction and productivity through the introduction of the new technology, "development services" or "unconventional inputs" such as agricultural research, education, and extension are required that broaden the range of alternative production possibilities available to the farm operators. New information which strengthens their capacity to make and execute decisions on the basis of more adequate knowledge of productive agricultural technology is of particular importance (Johnson, B. F. and Mellor, J. W., 1961). In Lampung currently in the dryland farming, the status of agricultural transformation is uncertain. Two hypotheses are proposed here that may reflect the status of agricultural transformation in Lampung as follows: Hypothesis 1: That the traditional agricultural technology brought over from Java has reached its equilibrium. Hypothesis 2: That a certain amount of new technology has been adopted by the farmers. Subhypotheses here are: (a) that whatever new technology has become available it has already been incorporated and new equilibrium has been reached; and (b) that there remains signifi- cant opportunity for greater use of the 10 currently available new technology for increas- ing food production and farm income. To explore these hypotheses the study was conducted in Various regions of Lampung where transmigration is con- centrated and the upland farming system for food crop pro- duction is the main agricultural activity. Lampung is divided into three Regional Development Areas (North, Central, and South) based on population density and administrative regions, and perhaps agroclimatic condi- tions (BAPEPPDA Lampung, 1979). See the map of Lampung province in Appendix A. The Third Indonesian Five Year Plan states that large scale mechanized public or private farms should also be encouraged outside Java to increase food production through the opening of new land. These large scale farms make extensive use of machinery and other modern inputs such as improved seeds, fertilizers, insecticides, herbicides, and better management. Examples of such farms are P.T. Mitsugoro, P.T. Daya Itoh, and P.T. Pago in Lampung pro— vince. These three farms have demonstrated the possibil- ities of turning alangZ land (Imperata cylindrica, which due to this tenacious grass before was considered as waste land) into productive ground. Food crops grown include corn, upland rice, and cassava. The yields were more than double that obtained on local traditional farms (Tsurumi, 1977). But in this study, these large scale highly mech- anized farms are excluded and attention was given only to 11 to the traditional and transitional small scale (subsis- tence) farms. This is not to say that the large scale mechanized farm is unimportant, but our emphasis here is to study those small scale subsistence farms. We assumed that the development of small scale farms in Indonesia will be the right strategy for increasing food production and income of millions of small farmers. This approach is supported by R. D. Stevens (1977) whose arguments can be summarized as follows: 1. Increasing food production on small farms is a primary route for improving national income dis- tribution. 2. In rural areas where unemployment is endemic and sufficient off-farm employment opportunities are unlikely available in the coming decade, due to a combination of rapid population growth and low rates of growth in employment in the service and particu- larly in the industrial sectors of developing nations. 3. The rising of food prices and global food scarcities has drawn attention to role of small farmers might play in food production. 4. Increasing energy costs for agricultural produc- tion, contributed sharply by recent sharp rises in petro prices and subsequent increases in the cost of nitrogen fertilizers. 12 Robert S. McNamara (1972), President of the World Bank, also registered concern about progress on small farms when he states "without rapid progress in small holder agriculture throughout the developing world, there is little hope of achieving long term stable economic growth or sig- nificantly reducing the level of absolute poverty." Fred Winch (1976) conducted research in Northern Ghana on costs and returns of six alternative rice production systems based on farm size and source of power for land preparation, and concluded that the small farm (3.9 acres) labor inten- sive approach produced substantial output and income to farmers and generated economic profits. This implied that, in a strategy to increase rice production and farm income, emphasis should be given to the development of small farms. These authorities have indicated that the solution to the national problems of food supply, income growth, and employment depends on the increasing productivity and creating new job opportunities among the vast number of small farmers throughout the developing nations. Korea is the example of a success in developing its agriculture through the develOpment of small farms under a noncommunist system as a strategy to increase food produc— tion and improve the welfare of the rural population.1 1See Workshop on the Development Strategies for Small Farmers, National Agricultural Economics Research Institutes, Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Republic of Korea, 1974. 13 The development of small scale farms is also con- sistent with the food policy in Indonesia, i.e., increasing per capita food consumption to improve nutritional standards, especially among the poorest groups of the society, and improvement of productivity of small farms in order to increase their incomes. At present, the new technology for increasing food production is chiefly offered through "BIMAS" (Mass guidance for increasing food production) for lowland rice. Less attention is given to the develop- ment of upland crops. Programs aimed at investigating upland cropping patterns are rarely applied in the outer islands. But in Lampung this cropping system research has been conducted by the two separate agencies: The "Tani Makmur Project" and the Central Research Institute for Agriculture (CRIA), which are operating independently. The Central Research Institute for Agriculture received tech- nical assistance from the International Rice Research Insti- tute (IRRI) and the Tank Makmur Project received technical assistance through Japanese bilateral foreign assistance and guidance from the Directorate General of Food Crops in the Ministry of Agriculture. In general, CRIA cropping system experiments feature higher level of cropping inten- sity than the Tani Makmur Project system, but the CRIA sys- tem has not yet been extensively tested in the farmer's fields, as has the Tani Makmur system. The Tani Makmur Project also enhances the farm organizations' ability to cope with the introduction of the new technology, 14 especially by farmer's training, distribution of agricul- tural inputs, and introduction of revolving funds. For the purpose of this study the Tani Makmur Cropping system experiment output is more relevant than the CRIA as a source of data, since we are focusing on an analysis of the farmers' cropping activities. 1.3 Objectives The primary aim of this study is to analyze the effects of the new technology on food production, resource use, productivity, and income of small farmers on the dry upland farming systems in Lampung. The specific objectives are: 1. To develop a comprehensive description of the crop- ping systems presently used on upland farms in the study area. 2. To identify and analyze the technological poten- tials presently available to increase food produc- tion and farm income, by studying the effects of new technology on cropping patterns, resource use and productivity, the use of new inputs, and on farm income. 3. To identify the major constraints facing small farmers in increasing food production and their income. 4. To derive the normative supply functions of major food crops, i.e., rice, corn, and cassava; and to 15 estimate their price elasticities of supply of these major crOps. 5. To derive from the result of the study some possible implications for development policies and strategies for increasing food production and income of small upland farmers in Lampung. To achieve the above objectives various analytical tools are available: (1) linear programming in its multi- faceted forms; (2) budgeting; (3) aggregate time series data analysis; (4) marginal analysis; and (5) simulation. These techniques are not necessarily exclusive, but each can be combined with one or more of the others. In general, the choice of analytical technique depends, most importantly, upon the availability of data and the purpose of the study. 1.4 The Research Approach Previous studies in Indonesia were conducted by McCarl (1978) who used a combination of linear programming and budgeting in studying the prospects of food production in Indonesia employing secondary data. Dibyo Prabowo (1977) conducted research in the Solo river basin (Central Java) using linear programming approach to determine the agri- cultural production activities to which farmers should allocate their scarce resources of land, labor, capital, and water so as to maximize net returns to the limited resources. He also determined how resource use and pro- duction are affected when certain constraints are relaxed. 16 The study shows that the irrigated farm has the highest potential for increasing farmers' income and unirrigated farm has the lowest potential for increasing small farm income. - These linear programming studies have been carried out in Lampung. Sultoni Arifin (1978) examined the effect of village labour resource on the feasibility of new crop- ping system in Central Lampung, by the use of linear pro- gramming approach. Rusdian Lubis (1978) examined the impact of cropping system on production, employment and income in resource management of upland areas in Central Lampung. Nurzaman Bachtiar (1978), examined the cash liquidity in adoption of the new cropping system in Central Lampung by using linear programming approach. All of these studies that have been conducted in Central Lampung used data from multiple cropping experimental plots of 1,000 square meters in one village (Bandarjaya) conducted by Central Research Institute for Agriculture in 1976/77. There is no clear way of how to adjust the data example of yields from the experimental plots to the real farm conditions (physically, economically, institutionally, etc.) on the small farm in Lampung. Wardhani (1976) used linear programming approach to examine various constraints for food production in the settlement areas of Lampung with the use of secondary data from various government agencies which most frequently are unreliable in develOping countries, so that the results of the analysis may be questionable. 17 Linear programming approach as an analytical tool has proved to be useful in the analysis of the small farmer's behavior in Indonesia as indicated by these studies. Other approaches could have been followed. Linear programming was selected because standardized tech- nique have been developed and it is to somewhat easier to apply than certain other methods such as simulation. The major problem has been data sources and quality. In this study, primary data were collected through survey methods in the areas where new technology has been introduced by "BIMAS" and/or "TANI MAKMUR PROJECT" to the small upland farms in Lampung province. The data provided estimates of relevant parameters under new and traditional technolo- gies on the representative operating farms. 1.3.1 The Analytical Framework To achieve the above objectives, the linear program- ming tool was chosen. Linear programming is highly suitable for analyzing farm adjustment problems and estimating supply functions in the approach of previous environment where no time series data exist. A static linear programming model of the "representative farm" in the study area will be used to obtain the optimum farm plan under traditional tech- nology and existing resource constraints as a base for com- parison. And then new activities, constraints, production coefficients reflecting the use of the new technology with modern inputs under farmers' conditions were introduced 18 into the model to find the optimal plan with new tech- nology. A comparative analysis of these farm plans was used to indicate the direct change in farm income, resource productivity, and cropping patterns that could result from full introduction of the new technology into the existing farming system. Static, normative supply curves of the major food crops under both technologies were derived by means of variable price (parametric) programming. Regression analy- sis was used to estimate the price elasticities of supply of the major food crops. It has been recognized that production and con— sumption considerations are both important for small farm- firms, so an attempt has to be made at integrating the two decisions into a single methodological framework. Endo- genous determination of consumption activities in linear programming allows the staple food to be grown for home consumption or for sale in the market. For example, the minimum level of rice consumption must be supplied from production or purchases. The use of linear programming as a computational tool in farm planning exercises is based on the hypothesis that peasant farmers tend to behave in ways which optimize their objective(s) given the constraints within which they operate. Risk factors are an important consideration in smallholder decision making. Therefore some method of incorporating risk factors into the linear programming 19 framework is needed. A number of approaches have been developed to take into account risk factors in linear pro- gramming models (McCarl, 1978; Andrew, 1976; Kennedy and Francisco, 1974), but there is yet no clear guidance for choosing the best method. Also, data such as time series on yield, prices, and‘production costs, needed to measure income variability may not be available. These data are required for the application of Quadratic Programming tech- niques to peasant farmer behavior under uncertainty. It is likely that peasant farmers are concerned about achieving a minimum level of production with certainty rather than minimizing income variance (Sow, 1974). In this study risk factors will only be incorporated in the analysis as con- sumption constraints for the major food crops. The general procedure to achieve the objectives involves (Low, 1974): (1) survey the specific areas in the three major development regions of Lampung using sample farm data to define representative farm resource situations and various alternative production possibilities in each region; (11) construct and structure the framework for the linear programming model by determining the technical coef- ficients, the operational constraints, activities or pro- cesses based upon the sample data, (iii) program the repre- sentative farm in order to carry out objectives 2, 3; and (iv) derive policy implications from the results of the analysis for development policies and strategies to increase farm income and food production. 20 1.3.2 Some Advantages and Limitations of Linear Programming Approach The main advantages of the linear programming tech- nique is that it can encompass in the analysis several com- modities as farm activities, seasonal labor, land constraints, more than one production technique, land-capital substitu- tion, and choice among several farm activities which are subject to different economic, resource and behavioral con- straints (Mudahar, 1974). Thus linear programming can be used to provide a more adequate analytical description of the whole-farm situation than other commonly used compu- tational techniques for farm planning. Another advantage of the linear programming technique is that it allows the determination of certain important economic measures of optimal plan. For example, it is possible to say how stable the optimal solution is, measured in terms of the changes in the net revenue of the enterprise needed to bring about a change in the level of activities in the optimal solution. The productivity of each farm resource can be assessed and the importance of the various planning constraints can be evaluated. A limitation of linear programming is that some of its assumptions may be unrealistic. For example, tradi- tionally in linear programming we assume that there is no farmer's enterprise preferences, they have perfect knowledge of various alternatives, there is no scale of economies in the processes, and risk and uncertainty do not enter 21 decision making. We also assume that farmers adjust to the optimal solution instantaneously, i.e., without a lag. Upton has discussed and provided an excellent summary of some of the methodological problems that comprise the most important limitations to the application of the linear pro- gramming method to subsistence farms (Upton, 1974). 1.3.3 Sources of Data For developing a farm plan by linear programming, data are typically needed on the production alternatives on the farm, the technical coefficients of production, prices of inputs and outputs at the farm level, and resources that are available on the farm. Data can be obtained from secondary or primary sources. Consideration of the rele- vance and reliability of the data on one hand, and time and funds/resources available on the other hand will determine the balance between the two sources. The use of secondary data sources are cheap, but the data available may not pro- vide reliable estimates of the parameters of the population being studied. In developing countries it is common that data from secondary sources are frequently unreliable. Official sources may not have the data needed or the avail- able data may be inaccurate. So the collection of the primary data from the field is the common need for social science research in developing countries. The empirical analysis in this study will draw mostly from primary data 22 sources, by interviewing a number of sample farmers in the study area. 1.3.4 Sampling Method and ‘ the Sample Size Sampling Method Lampung province is administratively divided into three Kabupatens (equivalent to the county level), i.e., South, Central, and North Lampung. Each Kabupaten is then subdivided into many Kecamatans (equivalent to the township level). South Lampung consists of twenty-four Kecamatans, Central Lampung with twenty-three Kecamatans, and North Lampung with twenty-four Kecamatans. Each Kecamatan again is divided into many villages. In terms of population density South Lampung is the most populated area (150-200 persons per square kilometer), next is Central Lampung (100-150 persons per square kilom- eter), and the least populated is North Lampung with less than fifty persons per square kilometer. The administrative regions are overlapped with the Development Regions as mentioned earlier. We believe that variation in population density is closely related to the length of time the area has been settled, and may be due to the variation in natural conditions, and infrastructure facilities, and consequently to the variation in cropping system and the kinds and the number of crops grown in each region. The Japanese Survey Mission for Agricultural Development in Lampung (1972) 23 concluded that each of the three Kabupatens has its own characteristics. In terms of the cropping ratio of food crops and cash crops (perennial), South Lampung tends to cash crops rather than food crops, whereas Central Lampung jpoints mostly to food crop production and North Lampung standing midway between the two areas. Production of the rnajor food crops by subregion (Kecamatan) in each region (Kabupaten) can be seen in Appendix B. These heterogenous conditions of the areas in llampung province in terms of population densities, length (Df settlement, cropping patterns and number of crops grown Sled us to the use of a two stage sampling method. The first fiatage involves purposive sampling up to the village level Eind.the second stage involves simple random sampling at the \Iillage level (Friedrich, 1977). By using stratification 13y region then every region (Kabupaten) was represented .in.this study. After two days of observations with extension per- Esonnel and local official of the three Kabupatens and after .in-depth discussion we came to the following conclusion. VVe should select village by the purposive method to be irepresentative of Lampung province as follows: South region (of Lampung represented by Pugung Raharja village; Central region of Lampung represented by Adiluih and Bulusari vil- lages; North region of Lampung represented by Tatakarya village. Since Central Lampung is more diversified in terms of crop and cropping pattern, two villages were selected 24 to represent this region. The selection of these four vil- lages was made after discussion with each village head and with "Mantri Pertanian Kecamatan" (extension worker at the township level). The villages that have been selected were judged to be typical of the area they represented in important attributes which influence the cropping patterns. From each Village selected, random sampling was used to select the representative farmers. Sample Size The sampling frame was drawn from the list of all :Earm cultivators in each village which is available in the trillage office. Statistical theory can help us determine the sample Esize for a particular survey in a universe provided we Specify the variance of the variable and the degree of éaccuracy of the estimates we want to derive (Yang, 1965). fPhis system will work well for problems where only one \Jariable is handled. However in this study we dealt with aseveral important variables such as labor utilization for (different enterprises, prices received, wage rates of laired labor, etc. These make it impossible to apply formal statistical procedure and to achieve statistical represen- ‘tativeness of the sample. A statistical formula was not used in this study to arrive at the number of farmers to be selected for interview. Instead, budget and time, and the availability 25 of the interviewer candidates, and experience of the researcher determined the size of our sample. The primary sampling unit was the family farm household representing Iboth the production unit as well as a consumption unit. 'The sampling frame was the whole family farm cultivators in 'the selected village, which can be found in the village :record. From the list of cultivators in each village a :random quota sample of twenty-three farm households were (drawn. Yang (1965) concluded that roughly twenty farms sflnould be included in each class (stratum) in order to make a: reliable comparison. Friedrich (1977) suggested twenty tx: twenty-five observations being necessary to produce reli- Eflole estimates for each group. The reliability of esti- Inates however, very much depends on the actual variability <>f the population. This then made up of the total sample (Bf ninety-two farm households from the four villages that Vvere selected. For a random selection in each village, tihe researcher asked for the help of the village head after linstructions were given by the researcher. This was done 1:0 hopefully reduce the suspicions from the village com- hnunity during the survey period. Then the village head :introduced the interviewers to the selected respondent farm Ilouseholds and briefly explained the purpose of the survey. 1Definition of household or farm family, those people eating from one pot (Norman, 1973). They also work together as a production unit. 26 1.3.5 Data Collection The survey schedules (questionnaires) were designed and developed for the purpose of collecting the needed data. [Data for only one year cropping cycle of 1978/1979 were <:ollected. Four agricultural university graduates helped ‘to conduct the interviews during the period of the survey :from August 1979 through December 1979. They are Extension Sipecialists (government employees) who are stationed in the aareas of study and are familiar with the local farm con— ditions.1 But on the other hand, there is a problem of ciual allegiance (dual loyalty one as extension worker/ snovernment employee and the other as an interviewer), which nuakes supervision or control difficult, or if not is impos- Stible (Friedrich, 1977). During the first month data were Cxollected on the previous years cropping cycle farm opera- tLion (September 1978-August 1979). Again with the same iJnterview procedure, the interview was repeated in September Elind October after the good "rapport"2 between the inter- \?iewer and the respondent farmer had been established. To iJmprove data reliability, then every month from September \ 1For detailed procedures in selection of the inter- ‘7iewer candidates see: Frank Lynch, S. J. (1976), Field Data (Zollection in Developing Countries: Experiences in Asia, E3eminar Report No. 4, June 1976, Agricultural Development (Bouncil, Inc., New York. 2"Rapport" could be described as genuine respect and understanding of both interviewer and the farmer, which to a large extent determines the quality of communication and the accuracy of response. 27 through December 1979, data were collected on family farm activities, off-farm activities, and consumption of the major food crops. This allowed for relatively short recall on the part of the respondent. More emphasis was given to the collection of data on labor use and family labor allo- cation during the peak demand for labor (September- December). The "periodic-visit survey" method was used, which represent the compromise between "single- and multi- visit" surveys, in collecting information on a few well- timed rounds organized around the completion of crucial phases, but also require a time period of a complete pro- duction cycle, usually one year (Friedrich, 1977). So the interview was based on monthly recall by the representative farmers. Each interview lasted from one hour to one-and-a- half hours for each respondent. Each interviewer was assigned one village in each region with which he is familiar. The problems encountered during the data collection throughout the survey period are similar to those discussed by Spencer (1972) and Norman (1973). 1.3.6 Construction of the Representative Farms The ideal approach is to program every farm unit, but cost of programming may be prohibitive, and it is not a practical approach. This led to the use of the repre- sentative farm, the representative of farm situation as the unit of linear programming analysis. In areas where there 28 is a reasonable homogeneity with respect to major resources particularly natural resources, such as soil type, topog- raphy and climate, linear programming can be used to obtain the solution toja "representative farm" situation in order to guide planning for individual farms. The usefulness of the representative farm approach is limited by the manner by which the representative farm is constructed. Collinson (1974) has discussed three alternative techniques for deriving representative farms. These are: (a) the identification of a particular farm as the typical farm, (b) the use of an "average farm" (derived from an average resource, input-output, and net price coef- ficients of a sample farm) as a representative farm (c) a "hypothetical" or synthesis of composite farm from different components of the population. It is not easy to find a single farm that could be validly considered typical in all respects. It requires consideration of a wide range of criteria. The selection and the construction of the criteria are difficult tasks and data for this purpose may not be available nor easy to collect. The use of "average farm" as the representative farm, brings with it the aggregation bias. Miller (1966), Buckwell (1972) and Carter (1963) have discussed the 29 aggregation bias inherent in the average farm approach. Aggregation bias exists when the sum of the solution from the individual farms in the set does not equal the estimate obtained by the optimum solution to the entire set directly. While the synthesis of composite farms reduces the aggrega- tion bias, it has the practical weakness in that it is diffi- cult to identify several institutional variables and human factors and their distribution within the population. These nontypical variables involve institutional constraints, motivations, preferences, managerial ability, etc. which have an important impact on farm organization, production efficiency, and earnings (Plaxico and Tweeten, 1962). The choice of the method for construction of the representative farm depends on the purpose for which the result of the study is to be used. In this study the objective is to identify the constraints and farm adjustments and to esti- mate the degree of farmers response to changes in prices of major food crops in a given area, so the use of the "average farm" as representative farm can be justified. The repre- sentative farm is based on data obtained from the survey. The farms in the sample were considered sufficiently similar with respect to the key variables that affect adjustment. In the study area all the sample farmers were trans- migrants from Java, and they were allocated land of about two hectares per household. Although there is a tendency toward land ownership concentration in the area of longer settlement, no one was found without land. Thus the level 30 of initial land resources for each individual farmer was rather homogeneous. 1.5 Organization of the Study This chapter was devoted to the problem definition and its setting, the statement of the objectives and methodo- logical approach for achieving these objectives. Chapter II will present the description of the farming system in the study area as revealed from the data obtained from the survey. The programming model containing activities, constraints, technical coefficients and prices will be discussed in Chapter III. In Chapter IV the results of the various applications of the models will be reported. The derived impact of the new technology on farm income, cropping patterns, resource use and its productivity will be discussed. In Chapter V normative supply schedules for major food crops (rice, corn, and cassava) both under tra- ditional and new technology will be presented. The response of the major food crops to changes in their prices will be examined. The effect of the new technology on the price elasticity of supply for major food crops will be dis- cussed. Chapter VI contains the summary along with a dis- cussion of the policy implications for development strategy from the result of the analysis, limitations and suggestions for further study. CHAPTER II DESCRIPTION OF THE FARMING SYSTEM IN THE STUDY AREA A good knowledge of the structure of the farming system in the area under study is required for proper repre- sentation of the agricultural conditions in a linear pro- gramming framework. This chapter will try to describe some important attributes of the farming system in the study area as revealed mostly by the study conducted by the author from July through December 1979. The description is pre- sented in terms of the characteristics of the representa- tive farms. The description of the farming system in Central Lampung will be supplemented with the results of the Base Line Survey conducted by Central Research Institutes for Agriculture (Djauhari, Aman, 1977). 2.1 Physical Characteristics of the Study Area There are about 46 million of hectares of red yellow podsolic soil out of a total of 200 million hectares of land in Indonesia. About 1.5 million hectares of this red- yellow podzolic soil is in Lampung. It is estimated that about 500,000 hectares of this land is covered with 31 32 alang-alang grass (Imperata cylindrica) as the result of the shifting cultivation in the past. 2.1.1 Soil and Climate of the Research Area The soil in the research area is a podzolic plain and generally flat, varying from red-yellow through brown in color. In general, this $011 is very porous and very low in fertility. Under these conditions and due to cutting of the forest and lack of agricultural land conservation, alang-alang grass (Imperata cylindrica) is the dominant vegetation. The soil has a low pH, is low in nitrogen, phosphorus and potassium content (McIntosh and Suryatna, 1976). The productive capacity of these soils has been seriously questioned by many agricultural scientists. In fact these areas have been described as alang-alang infested waste lands due to production constraints such as low inherent soil fertility, excessive drainage and low pH. But on the positive side there are several assets. The rainfall and its distribution are very good for a year around upland crop production. The average monthly rain- fall during the period of 1969-1975 is shown in Figure 2.1. The driest month is in July and wettest month is in March. The rainfall is well distributed and based on this data, the Lampung region falls within Type DZ in the agro- climate map. Rainfall exceeds 200 mm (80 inches) for six months and 100 mm for three months. The remaining three 33 Rainfall (mm Mm; 360 200 I00 Fig.’2,1. Monthly rainfall pattern in Bandarjaya, Central Lampung, Indonesia, 1970-76. Source: CRIA, Bogor, Indonesia, 1977. 34 months are drier but average rainfall is only a little less than 100 mm. Since the soils are well drained, the heavy rains during the rainy season do not inhibit upland crops production, and a year around cropping is possible. Run off problems are minimized by the rapid infiltration of the rain water. Consequently, the soils are acid and leached. But fortunately the soils do not contain exces- sive levels of aluminum. There is sufficient clay and organic matter to hold applied nutrients but fixation of phosphorus is not a problem. So, these soils can be highly productive if managed properly (Central Research Institute for Agriculture, 1977). 2.2 Land Use Most of the transmigrants received two hectares of land. But they could only cultivate less than a hectare by depending on the family as a source of labor. Most of the farmers have only subsistence farming in the upland areas using multiple cropping with the major crops of upland rice, corn, and cassava or sometimes with legumes. The research area can be divided into two cate- gories based on the length of settlement. These are: Category I - Old alang-alang areas (Pugung Raharja, Adiluih, and Bulusari Villages) Category II - Newly Opened areas (Tatakarya Village which was settled about six years ago). 35 Usually the farmers start land preparation in the beginning of the rainy season (in September) and planting in October and November each year with rice, corn, and cassava in a mixed cropping System. 2.3 Crop Productions and Cropping Patterns There were nine crops grown in the study area during the survey period. These crops included cereals, root crops, and legumes, and perennial crops. They are grown either as a sole or as a mixture, but are mostly grown as a mixture (multiple cropping or intercropping). Tech- nical reasons for mixed cropping are: complementary relation- ships derived by the crops, soil protection and reduction in the incidence of disease and pest attacks. The socio- economic reasons included the maximization of returns by more efficient uses of resources and higher total output and the need for security by more frequent harvest. The crop combinations and the number of farmers growing each combination are presented in Table 2.1. The table shows that the number of farmers that practiced the mixed cropping system accounted for 60 per- cent, 70 percent, 98 percent, and 48 percent for Adiluih, Bulusari, Pugung Raharja, and Tatakarya villages respec- tively. The newly Opened areas, Tatakarya had the lowest number of farmers with multiple cropping system in their farming operation. Perhaps they are not yet fully adjusted to the local farming conditions. 36 Table 2.l.--Number and Percentage of Farmers by Cropping Patterns of the Representative Farms in Lampung. Areas/Villages Cropping Patterns* Adiluih Bulusari Eggggga Tatakarya No. % No. % No. % No. % l. C + ULR / CV 4 20 8 38 - - 16 69 2. ULR / CV 2 10 10 47 - - 6 26 3. ULR 4 20 2 9 - - - - 4. CV 5 25 10 5 - - 20 87 5. LLR 8 40 1 - - - l 4 6. ULR - SB - - - - 13 65 l 4 7. C + ULR - SB 5 25 - - 2 10 - - 8. C + SB / CV - - - - 8 40 - - 9. C + ULR/CV - - - - 5 25 - - 10. SB-SB-SB/CV - - - - 6 30 - - 11. C/COC 4 20 - - - - - - 12. GNDT - - - - - - 4 l7 l3. PEP - - - - l 5 2 8 14. C / CV - - - - - - 2 8 15. ULR + SB/COC 1 5 - - - - - - 16. COF + COC l 5 2 9 - - - - l7. CLO + COC 3 15 - — - - - - 18. COC/FC 2 10 l 5 5 25 - — 19. COF/FC 3 25 3 l3 - - - - 20. PEP + CLO - - - - 5 25 - - 21. CLO/FC - - - - 3 15 - - Source: Field Survey. *+ Two crops planted together at the same time or the second crop planted within a week after the first crOp. / The second crop planted a month later after the first crop. - The second crop planted after the first crop harvested. / The last crop planted between border or fencing or between the existing perennial crop. For explanation of abbreviations, see Table Cl, Appendix C. 37 Table 2.2 shows the number of hectares devoted to different crop enterprises by the representative farmers in the study area during the survey period. Mixed cropping accOunted for 61 percent, 70 percent, 77 percent, and 68 percent for Adiluih, Bulusari, Pugung Raharja, and Tatakarya villages respectively. Both in terms of the number of farmers and the total area, multiple cropping or mixed cropping is dominant cropping pattern in the study area. It can be also expected that the longer the area is settled, the more land will be devoted to perennial crOps such as clove, coconut, coffee, and pepper. Such crops occupy very little cultivated land on farms in Tatakarya, the newly settled area, and average 0.2 ha or 13 percent for Bulusari, 0.21 ha or 14 percent for Adiluih, 0.35 ha or 24 percent for Pugung Raharja villages. Area devoted to food production decreases as the longer the area has been settled. This can be explained as follows: First, the deterioration of soil fertility, which more and more suitable for perennial crops rather than for food crop pro- duction. Second, land ownership concentration increases as the longer the area settled, so perennial crops again is the answer to cope with labor shortage for these larger farms, since perennial crops require less labor both in the total labor per hectare and seasonality in labor use. Third, that relative price between food crops and perennial crops deteriorated, may be due to the effect of government policy and external effect of the increasing demand for coffee, 38 Table 2.2.--Average Area Devoted to Each Cropping Pattern by the Representative Farms in Lampung. Areas/Villages Cropping Patterns* Adiluih Bulusari Eggggga Tatakarya (ha) (ha) (ha) (ha) 1. C + ULR f CV 0.28 0.40 - 0.62 2. ULR / CV 0.18 0.31 - 0.19 3. ULR 0.17 0.10 - - 4. CV 0.16 0.27 - 0.37 5. LLR 0.25 0.23 - 0.02 6. ULR - SB - - 0.36 0.03 7. C + ULR - SB - - 0.28 - 8. C + SB f CV 0.11 - - - 9. ULR + C/CV - - 0.20 - 10. SB-SB-SB/CV - - 0.24 - ll. CV/CO 0.10 - 0.02 — 12. GNDT - - - 0.06 13. PEP - — - - 14. C + CV - - - 0.09 15. ULR + SB/CO 0.02 - - - l6. COF + CLO 0.02 - — - l7. CLO + CO - - - - 18. COF/FC 0.10 0.05 - - l9. CO/FC 0.09 0.04 - - 20. CLO + PEP - - 0.12 - 21. CLO - - 0.23 - Average Size of Farm 1.48 1.44 1.45 1.38 Average Food Crops 1.27 1.25 1.10 1.38 Average Perennlal 0.21 0.19 0.35 0.00 Crops Source: Field Survey. *For explanation of the abbreviations, see Table C1, Appendix C. 39 clove, by international market. Government policies with respect to food and price stabilization in a low level (consumer oriented policies) for the price of food crops, e.g., rice, corn. There is no such effort for perennial crops which is promoted for export commodities. The likely impact to the farmer's decision in the longer run is to devote more land for perennial crop production andlless for food crops. This trend is unfavorable or contradicted with the self-sufficiency food program at the national level. The transmigration area is expected at least to become self- sufficiency in food, and some food surplus to be supplied to the city, e.g., Jakarta. This hope may not be ful- filled if this trend continued. It seems there is a conflict between food production self-sufficiency program at the national level and in the micro level or farm level in the transmigration area in Lampung. 2.4 Technology of Agricultural Production Two kinds of agricultural production technology found in the study area, the traditional and the new tech- nologies. The traditional technology are two types, one is the indigenous traditional technology with shifting cul- tivation or slash and burn is still exists mostly practiced by the indigeneous population (Lampungnese) and the second type is locally develOped by the transmigrants in their settlement areas, e.g., mixed cropping and/or sole cropping without use of any new modern inputs. The practice of 40 multiple cropping may be influenced by multiple cropping system in Java, the origin of the transmigrants. In this study the traditional technology considered is the one that locally developed by the transmigrants only, not included the shifting cultivation. New technology is use of new inputs and/or new techniques such as the use of fertilizers, insecticides, improved seeds, tractor for land preparation to the traditional farming. The traditional food crop pro- duction technology currently being replaced partly by the new technology through the extension activities of BIMAS and TANI MAKMUR PROJECT, which introduce the use of improved seeds, fertilizers, insecticides/pesticides to the existing locally traditional cropping systems. Seeds use are mostly local varieties for rice, cassava, soybean. Corn seeds used were improved varieties (such as Metro, DMR). Fertilizers input is considered to be the main modern input of the new technology. On the average about forty kilograms of urea and twenty kilograms of phosphate fertilizers and two liters of insecticides were used per hectare by the representative farm in the study area, much less than recommended level at 200 kilograms of urea and phosphate fertilizers. Land prep- aration starting in August/September up to November] December. Land preparation by manual labor and some with the use of animal power both for traditional and new tech- nologies are existing in the study area. Use of tractors and other farm machineries are absent in the small upland farm operations. 41 The large scale highly mechanized farms do make extensive use of machinery and other modern inputs such as improved seeds, fertilizers, insecticides, herbicides, and better management including better products, processing and marketing. Examples of such farms are P.T. Mitsugoro, P.T. Daya Itoh, P.T. Pago and other similar estate farms in Lampung, both foreign and domestic enterprises. Food crops grown including upland rice, corn or maize, and cassava as a single crops or pure stands. The yields were more than double that obtained on local traditional farm. However these large scale highly mechanized farms were not included in this study because of the particular objectives as has been mentioned before was emphasized on small upland farms. 2.5 Some Demographic Characteristics of the Representative Family Farms in the Study Area In the following table shows the main demographic characteristics of the representative family farms popula- tion in the study area. Sex ratios in all villages are above one, that is the proportion of males is more than 50 percent. The sex ratios of the active populations are below 60 per- cent and vary between 53.8 percent to 59.4 percent. The dependence ratio1 is the highest in the newly settled area, i.e., Tatakarya Village with a 0.87 ratio. This can be 1Dependent ratio is the ratio between the number of dependent children plus the number of dependent aged and the number of active population. See Table 2.3. 42 >w>usm UHm0m "muusom 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0000 000500 mmmnm>a .0 IIIMIII A0 + 00 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00000 0000000000 .0 .000 00000 00.00. 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 0000000000 m>0uoa .0 AOHO mama» m0 Hm>ov 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 0004 pamoamaoa .0 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 000m: 00 0000000000 .0 1000 00000 00.0. 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 000000ao 000000000 .0 mmHmEmm .02 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 n 00000 xom .0 moan: .oz mxumxmume chumnmm Hummsasm 0500 a mcsmsm . c. .U mowumwumuomumno Oflcmmumofimo 0000000> .mcsofimq :0 mOHOcomsom Emma o>0umucomouoom cry 00 mOHum0uouooumco 00cmm0mOEmc mEOmnn.m.m OHOME 43 understandable since most of the family heads are rela- tively young with more dependent children. This ratio is 50 percent for the Tatakarya Village. The number of dependent aged (over 65 years old) is low in all the vil- lages. The average family size in the study area is 5.7 persons. The highest size of the family is in the newly settled area, i.e., six persons for Tatakarya, 5.9 persons for Bulusari, 5.6 persons for Pugung Raharja, and 5.3 persons for Adiluih. 2.6 Educational Level of Representative Farm Household's Head The following table shows the educational level of the representative farm household's head for each village. On the average it is very low at 3.3 years varying from 0 to 6 years. This is near to the illiterate level. They can hardly keep records on their farming operations. Table 2.4.--Average Representative Farm Household's Head Educational Level. Village Aviéige Efiucati°n $231136 (years) years) Size 1. Tatakarya 41.6 3.2 6.0 2. Bulusari 43.4 3.6 5.9 3. Pugung Raharja 45.3 3.0 5.6 4. Adiluih 48.0 3.4 5.3 Overall Average 46.1 3.3 5.7 Source: Field Survey 44 A. Raji Ahmed (1972) in his research on the size of cattle feeding operations has concluded that the suc- cess of the optimum size unit is a function of quality of the managerial inputs, the managerial behavior of which is characterized by willingness to accept a higher degree of risk, appreciation for and application of scientific criteria in decision making, and higher levels of formal education. The low level of agricultural productivity in this transmigration area may be related also to the high risk factors in adapting the new profitable technology. So, it is not just enough to provide them with more profitable new production techniques, but also measures to reduce risk to an acceptable level are required. For more detailed dis- cussion of these problems, see Ruttan and Hayami (1971) and comment by George L. Beckford. Supply of goods and services and provision of better institutions and better Opportunities may not be sufficient to achieve the farm income goals although they are necessary conditions for the development of the small farmers. The managerial skills of the small farmers should be improved for small farmer devel— opment. 2.7 Farm Labor Force The family is the major source of the farm labor force. The representative farm in the study area on the average consists of 5.7 persons. A detailed composition of the labor force of the representative family farms can be 45 seen in Table 2.5 which is recorded at the beginning of the survey. The available labor on the representative family farm is 2.75 adult male equivalents. The avail- ability of family labor is determined by many factors such as the family structure (age and sex), health, nutrition, major occupation of each member of the family, customs, and job opportunities outside the farm. It is estimated that about 240-260 days of farm work per year for adult male workers and only about 125 days of farm work for women are available for the representative family. As one would anticipate in a society where landless does not exist, most work is undertaken on the farm by the family itself. In Pugung Raharja Village the total labor inputs by the representative farm is 315 mandays equivalent per year, of which about 92 percent come from the family sources and only about 8 percent from hired daily labor. This labor hiring activity is small, but it may be important due to their use in the critical season such as for land preparation, weeding, and harvesting. Monthly labor inputs and wage rates are presented in Tables 2.6 through 2.9. Exchange labor is common in the study area ranging from 7 to 20 percent of the total labor input on the farm. The highest percentage of exchange labor is found in the rela— tively new settled area, i.e., Tatakarya and becomes less and less as the area becomes longer settled. Exchange labor tends to switch to hired labor system, especially when cash crops and perennial crops become more important 46 Table 2.5.--Representative Farm Family Composition by Age Groups in Lampung. Average Number of Persons in Age Groups (years) Average Work Villa e Family Force 9 Size Available Less Over (person) (man—day)* Than 8-14 15-64 64 8 l. Tatakarya 1.70 1.20 3.10 - 6 0 2.50 2. Bulusari 1.50 1.10 3.30 - 5 9 2.80 3' Pugung 1.00 1.56 3.05 0.09 5.7 2.90 Raharja 4. Adiluih 1.00 1.10 3.15 0.05 5.3 2.78 Average 1.30 1.24 3.15 0.03 5.7 2.75 Source: Field Survey *Marwoto (1975) has calculated the available labor force for a family in Lampung area with unit labor as follows: Adult Male (Father) Adult Female (Mother) Children less than 8 years : Children 8-14 years old Children over 14 years Old Other Adult DJO O labor unit (if all children under 12 years old) (some children over 5 years old) (if all children over 12 years old) (if not attending school) >0>09m c0000 “mousom 47 000 00 00 00 0000000000 000 00 m0 mom 00000 000 00 0 0 00 0000 000 00 N 0 00 00:0 000 0 N 0 0 002 000 00 0 0 00 00000 000 00 0 0 0 00002 000 00 0 0 00 00000000 000 00 m 0 00 0000000 000 00 0 00 0 00050000 000 N0 0 0 00 00020>oz 000 00 0 0 00 0000000 000 00 0 0 00 000500000 ..000 00 0 0 00 000000 A>0o\£mflmsmv Amwmccmzv Am>0pcmzv Ammmpcmzv Amxmpcmzv moumm Honmq 00900 00900 Honmq 30:02 0003 00009 0000: monocoxm maflfimm .mcsmqu :0 0000000> nflsawcdv mfiumm o>0000comoumom 0:0 co moumm 0003 cam £0202 an musmcH Honmq Hmuoall.m.m 00208 48 .000 .mm 0cm om .00 00 0000500 00 £0023 00:00 000 000000000 000050000 00200 .0000 000x003 00000: 008000 :00 000050000 0020 >0>05m 00000 “00050m 000 00 00 00 0000000000 «New mm 00 mm0 00009 omv I I I I 0050 omv I I I I 0050 omv 0 I I 0 >02 000 00 I I 00 00000 omv mm 00 0 0m 5000: omv 00 m m m0 00050000 com mm m 0 mm 0005006 oom mm 0 0 mm 00080000 oom m0 0 0 0m 00080>oz oom ow m 00 mm 0000000 000 mm m m 00 000000000 ..omv 00 m0 0 0 000000 A>0o\£0005mv 000000020 Am>0000zv Am>0000zv Am>000020 «000000 00000 00000 00000 00000 00:02 0003 00009 0000: 00c0£0xm 000800 .0050800 00 A000000> 0000505m. 08000 000800 0>00 I0000000000 0:0 00 £0002 >0 005000 00000 00009 000 00000 0003 >000QII.0.N 00009 >w>usm onHm "mousom 49 OOH m.m m.m m.Nm momucmoumm mHm NN NN omN Hmuoe com NH N . mH umsmaN omm mN N m ON aHsn omm NH N o NH mean omm HQ N m Nm an: oom NH N u mH HHHQN oom NH N . mH scum: com ON N . NH mumsunmm com mm m w om mumscmn coo H« v m Nm umgfimomo com Hm m m mN umnsm>oz omm ON m N mH umnouoo omm mm . v Hm umnEmummm A>m0\nmflmsmv Amwmncwz. Am>m©cmzv Amamccmzv Amwmoamz. mwumm Honmq uonmq Honmq uonmq nucoz mmmz Hmuoe Umuflm mwcmnoxm kHHEmm .mcsasmq CH AmmmHHH> anumsmm mcsmsmv mEHmm >HHEmm m>flu Imucmmmummm mnu co sumo: ma musmcH Honmq Hmuoa 6cm mmumm mmmz >HHMQII.@.N anma 50 >m>usm camflm "mouaom OOH O OH OO mmmucmoumm ONO ON OO OON Hmuoa OOO OH . . OH OHOO OOO O u u O mean OOO OH I - OH Om: OOO HN O I ON HHnma OOO OH I I OH comm: OOO OH . - OH Oumauawm OOO O - . ON Oumscmn OOO HN . O OH umnawomo OOO OO O HH OO nmnam>oz OOO OO O OH NO umnouoo OOO OO O O ON ungmummO OOO NO O O ON umsmn¢ A>m0\£mflmzm. Am>m©cmzv Amwmvcmzv Amwmvcmzv Ammmocmz. mmumm Momma Honmq uonmq Momma sumo: mmmz Hmuoa vmuflm wmcmnoxm kHHEmm .mchEmA cH AmmmHHO> mwumxmumsv \ mEHmm m>Humucmmwummm may :0 wmumm mmmz wawma cam mysmcH Hogan hanpc02Il.m.N magma 51 in the areas. Exchange labor is mostly evident during the planting and weeding seasons. There is no clear social arrangement on how to use and repay exchange (gotong royong) labOr, but everybody understands and agrees that the farmer or members of his family can work as repayment. There is no standard time within which to repay borrowed labor, but on the average the time span for repayment is within two weeks (Sultoni Arifin, 1978). In this study exchange labor will be treated as family labor and should be repaid in labor within a month. Hired labor generally is obtained simply on the daily hiring basis. The average wage rates for hired labor in the study area ranged from Rp500 to Rp600 per day, which included two meals, breakfast and lunch. These meals accounted for Rp 50 and Rp 150 respectively. There is not much variation of wage rates between seasons, except for rice harvesting with the "bawon system." The bawon or "harvest share" is common in the study area for rice harvesting. In the traditional bawon system, rice harvesting takes the form of a community activity in which all or most of the community members can participate and receive a certain share of output. The owner normally gives a harvest share to the harvesters of one-sixth to one- fifth of what they harvested in Lampung area. This is called "bawon." So, the amount of bawon received depended upon the amount harvested, which in turn related to age and sex. The value of bawon in money terms was between Rp 1000 52 and Rp 1300 per day in 1979 in Lampung for adult males, which was more than double the average daily wage rates at Rp 500. That is why workers prefer joining the rice har— vest rather than other farm activities. Hiring labor with bawon system for rice harvesting is also as a social device to redistribute output or income to the less beneficial groups in the village society. For more detailed discus- sion on the bawon system and recent change in this system see Collier gt El- (1973) and Sturgess and Wijaya Hesti (1979). The family labor is the most important in the rela- tively new settled area, where cash flow is also the lowest, i.e., Tatakarya. The higher percentage of hired labor is in the older settled area with 18 percent for Adiluih, 14 per- cent for Bulusari, and only 9 percent for Tatakarya Village. In Pugung Raharja Village, the oldest settlement, hired labor is only 8.6 percent. This low percentage of hiring labor may be due to differences in crop production emphasis and cropping system. In Pugung Raharja soybeans and corn are the major crops rather than rice as in the other vil- lages. So the labor distribution is more even in Pugung Raharja Village during the year, because weeding and har- vesting is less critical seasons for labor demand for both crops. It is also true that land devoted to food crop is the smallest at 1.10 ha in Pugung Raharja from 1.45 hectare area under cultivation (see Table 2.2). But there is no 53 landless in this area. Cropping intensity may also be higher in this area. In this study it is sufficient to measure labor use in mandays.; The assumption in measuring manday units is that the length of the working day is in part dependent on the cultural pattern of the society. It is about eight hours per day in Lampung area, starting early in the morning at 7 o'clock up to 12 o'clock, then resting for two hours, and then starting again at 2 o'clock up to 5 or 6 o'clock in the afternoon. Another problem in measuring labor inputs is what weight to use in aggregating man, woman, and children days of work. Work may be affected by the age and sex of the worker as well as by the task being performed and the cul- ture in the society. Norman (1973) has estimated for North Nigeria the weights to a common denominator for converting to labor units. His assumption is that initially there is a positive correlation with age and then a negative corre- lation with age. He also assumes that the physical produc- tivity of woman is lower than man. The following table shows the Norman equivalent to adult male worker. Marwoto (1975) has calculated the available number of labor units for settlement areas in Indonesia as is shown in Table 2.11. 54 Table 2.lO.--Man Equivalents Used in the RERU Farm Manage- ment Studies. Labor Class ; Age gZiEV:?:::S Small child Less than 7 0.00 Large child 7-14 0.50 Female adult 15-64 0.75 Male adult 15-64 1.00 Female adult 65 or more 0.50 Male adult 65 or more 0.50 2.8 Farm Capital The two main inputs of traditional agriculture are labor and land. The amount of capital and the proportion of income invested are very low. Mellor (1967) has, how- ever, emphasized that saving and investment are functions of two main factors: (a) the attitude toward saving, invest- ment, and consumption; (b) the low level of capital forma- tion in traditional agriculture is not necessarily because the capacity of saving is low but because of the low rates of return on investment. Most of the capital is actually simple tools or improvements produced mainly by labor. At this low level of technilogy the productivity of addi- tional capital of this type is very low. Capital in farming includes items such as machines, tools, buildings, roads, land improvements, tree crops, livestock, seeds, fertilizers, etc. These assets are 55 Table 2.11.--Table of Conversion of Various Working Age and Different Sex for Settlement Areas. Labor Class Male Adult Equivalents Adult male (father) : 1.00 labor unit Adult female (mother) : 0.30 (if all children under 5 years) : 0.50 (if some children over 5 years) 1.00 (if all children over 12 years) Children less than 8 years : 0.00 labor unit Children 8-14 years : 0.20 labor unit 00 O 0 U" C labor unit (if attend- ing school full time) Children over 14 years Children over 14 years : 1.00 labor unit (if not attending school) Other adults : 1.00 labor unit Source: P. T. Agrindo/Harrison Fleming. 56 usually classified into fixed capital (such as machines, tools, buildings, land improvements, tree crops) with a productive life more than a production cycle;1 and working capital or Operating capital (such as seeds, fertilizers, insecticides/pesticides, hired labor) which are used up in a single production cycle. The level of fixed capital in the study area is very low compared to labor. Use of capital equipment to substi- tute for labor is very small. Each family farm owns three hoes, three sickles, one chopping knife, and three "arit" which is used for weeding and cutting grasses. The total value is about Rp 7,800 ($12). In fact most of other capital costs such as in tree crops, land improvement, livestock are the embodiment of labor provided by the farmers. Livestock activity is not important in the study area, restricted only to the backyard poultry. Operating capital is the value of fertilizer, seed, insecticides/pesticides, and hired labor used in the pro- duction process. Use of hired labor and seed do not neces- sarily mean cash expenditures since most of the labor hired is paid in kind (bawon system) and seed used is mainly saved from the farmer's previous harvest. Fertilizer is Rp 80 per kilogram supplied by the government at subsidized and con- trolled proces. lProduction cycle in this study can be grouped into: (1) clearing and preparation of land; (2) sowing, planting, and fertilizing; (3) cultivation--weeding, and (4) harvest- ing. 57 Personal saving is the main source of cash for pur- chase of operating capital. Institutional credit is not available except for the farmers who joined the "BIMAS" program. Table 2.12 shows the cash expenditures of the representative farm on purchased inputs by month. These are the amounts estimated that have been spent on hired labor, fertilizers, seeds, insecticides/pesticides, and for food and drinks for hired and exchange labor during the 1978-1979 production season. The total cash expenditure for one year production cycle amounted to Rp 30,000, Rp 54,250, and Rp 18,000 for Tatakarya, Buluwari and Adiluih, and Pugung and Raharja respectively. 58 Table 2.12.-—Cash Expenses by the Representative Farms by Month in Lampung. Cash Expenses (Rupiah) Month Tatakarya Adiluih & Bulusari Pugung Raharja August 6000 4500 - September 1000 5000 1500 October 9600 19750 1500 November 325 5000 4500 December 500 4000 2000 January 1000 5000 1500 February 500 2000 3000 March 500 4500 1000 April 7000 500 1000 May — 500 1000 June - 2000 1000 July - 1500 1000 Total 29250 54250 18000 Source: Field Survey CHAPTER III THE STRUCTURE OF LINEAR PROGRAMMING MODEL OF THE REPRESENTATIVE FARMS FOR THE STUDY AREA 3.1 Introduction A typical decision faced by management is the optimum allocation of scarce resources. Management's task is to achieve the best possible outcome with the given resources. Linear programming is very useful technique in aiding management for making these decisions. This new technique has been accepted by farm management workers in many countries to solve management problems of individual farms (Yang, 1965). Linear programming problems must meet the following requirements (Lee, 1976). a. The objective function: Linear programming problems must have an explicit objective criterion to opti- mize. The objective function may be one of either maximization or minimization of the criterion. b. Limited resources: In order to apply linear pro— gramming, a decision problem must involve activ- ities that require consumption of limited resources. 59 60 The amount of limited resources is usually expressed as constraints for the problem. c. Linearity and additivity: The primary requirement of linear programming is the linearity in the objective function and in the constraints. The word "linear" implies that relationships among decision variables must be directly proportional. d. Divisibility: Linear programming requires complete divisibility of resources utilized and the units of the decision variables. In other words, frac- tional values of decision variables and resources must be permissible to obtain optimal solution. e. Deterministic: In linear programming all model coefficients (e.g., unit profit contribution of each product and the amount of available resources) are assumed to be known with certainty. In other words, linear programming implicitly assumes a decision problem in a static time period. Linear programming is usually applied to the complex prob- lems which involve many interacting variables that con- tribute to objective criterion functions. In linear programming, if a problem involves n- decision variables and m-constraints, the typical linear programming model can be constructed mathematically, as either a maximization or a minimization formulation. where: 61 The maximization problem, n Maximize Z = Z Cj Xj subject to aij Xj i bi (i = l, 2, . ., m) Xj 3 0 (j = l, 2, , n) The minimization problem n Minimize A = Z Cj Xj i=1 subject to aij Xj 3 bi (i = l, 2, . ., m) Xj 3 0 (j = l, 2, ., n) only nonnegative level of each decision variables will be considered. Cj = unit contribution rate, the marginal contribu- tion of each decision variable. Xj = decision (or activity) variables aij = technological coefficients, how much a resource is required for each activity unit bi = given resources or the amount of resources available (right hand side value) 62 For a mathematical formulation of linear programming models in matrix notation, see Heady and Candler (1973). The assumptions of linear programming include addivity of resources and activities, linearity of objective function, nonnegativity of decision variables, divisibilities of activities and resources, finiteness of the activities and resource restrictions, proportionality of the activity level to resources and single value expectation, also discussed by Agrawal and Heady (1972). In the following section, the three essential ele- ments of linear programming, the objective function, the activities and system constraints, will be discussed. 3.2 The Objective Function It is likely that small farmers entertain a number of objectives (e.g., profit or income maximization, output maximization, cost minimization, security) although they are not necessarily exclusive, Schultz (1964) and Hopper (1965) believe that peasant farmers are profit maximizers. Miller and Charles (1964) argued that, "profit maximization is not always the primary goal of farm management. Others demand sure and sometimes substantial returns before they risk additional operating capital for problems that are compounded by great variability in production, and a high level of risk and uncertainty. Under such circumstances it is difficult to follow rigorous decision-making cri- teria. As a result, many of these farmers do not follow 63 a management strategy that would maximize their profits but instead follow a strategy that minimizes costs." Norman (1973) concluded that for small farmers in Zaira area in Northern Nigeria, both security and profit maximization were relevant goals. Heyer (1971) in her study on con- straints on peasant farmers in Kenya had difficulties in finding out what it is the subsistence farmers aimed for. Subsistence farmer's objectives are ambiguous, but then she suggested, "insuring an adequate food supply during a drought years, producing preferred variety of diet, maxi- mizing the number of people fed, maximizing the market value of output" were possible alternatives to be considered. The complexities of small farmer objectives make it diffi- cult to operationalize their decision in a linear pro- gramming framework. Risk factors are an important consideration in small holder decision making. Risk aversion is a rational and almost universal characteristic of small farmers, particu- larly with respect to the family food subsistence crops. A number of recent studies have cited the importance of risk on the decision making by peasant farmers (Norman, 1973; Dillon and Anderson, 1971; Woglin, 1975). As recent empirical studies of peasant behavior indicate, "safety first criteria” tend to be followed whenever the satisfac- tion of the basic needs may be at stake. In this study the safety first criterion will be used in the formulation of the linear programming. Small 64 farmers in the study area are assumed seeking security and risk aversion (such as provided by the practice of multiple cropping) as well as maximization of net farm income. The security objective will be incorporated in the matrix table as constraints, so that necessary amounts of rice, corn, cassava for meeting the minimum family consumption levels will be obtained first. According to this rule, an impor- tant motivating force for the decision maker in managing the productive resources that he controls and, in particu- lar, in choosing among technological Options is the security of generating returns large enough to cover subsistence needs (Moscardi and Janvry, 1977). The required amounts of food crop consumption were estimated from the simple con- sumption survey conducted by the researcher in the study area. It was found that rice is the most preferred food staple, then corn and the last one is cassava. These con- sumption requirements can be either produced or bought. Net farm income in this study will be expressed as "gross margin." Gross margin is defined as the total value of production less variable costs of production. In other words, net return to resources such as land and labor which are considered "fixed" in this study. Fixed cost other than land and labor are negligible in the study area. 65 3.3 Activities in the Model There are seven groups of activities which will be included in the model for the representative farm of Tatakarya Village: (a) Crop production activities (b) Labor hiring activities (c) Fertilizers, insecticides, food crop buying activities (d) Food crop consumption activities (e) Crop selling activities (f) Capital borrowing activities (g) Transfer activities (a) Crop Production Activities The crop production activities for the representa- tive farm are outlined in Table 3.1, Column Al through A14. They consist of four food crops: upland rice, corn, soy- beans, and cassava in a single crop stand and in mixed crops. They are comprised of four sole crops (upland rice, corn, soybean, and cassava), three crop mixtures of two crops (upland rice f cassava, corn f cassava, upland rice - soybeans) and one three crop mixture (upland rice + corn + cassava) enterprises. These identified crop production possibilities are the most important production opportun- ities with respect to the area devoted to each crop/crop mixture and the number of farmers involved. They are sig- nificant in terms of their contribution to family food €56 O N. n O - - n - - O O - O O H a an: NOOOOO ON O w. a NH . u u u . O OH u OH O O s as: means: ON O .w u u - - u - - O O - n O O u as: OOOOOO ON O w. OH OH O u u - u u u - u u - c a: Hausa: ON O W OH - O .. u - .. u u u u u n n 9. 33.. ON O w. - - u - - u - n - u u u u u .u. NOIRH: ON O w n u . ON NN - - . OH OH O O OH O a: OOOOH: NN O w. ON - .. .. .. .. .. OH - - u u .. .. 9. g HN O .w - - - - - - - OH - .. - - .. .. O. and. ON O .w ON - - - - - - - - - O - u u a: sauna: OH O .w - - - - - O - - - N - N O O .O. gonna: OH O N. O - - - - OH NH - OH O . O O O O! >Osz: OH O .w O c u u . O OH - - O O u u O u: gonna: OH O .w OH - - - - - - - - - - O - O HO. manna: OH O w. ON OH O - - NH NH .. NH O O OH NH NH H! 83: OH OH w O OH OH - .. - .. O - OH OH . u u H! .53.. OH OH .w O - O - . ON O - OH O u - - N O. .83.: NH OH N. O NH OH . - I OH NN O NH ON NH OH HH n: OOIOHN HH ON .w s - N O O OH OH O O NH ON OH OH OH a: OOOOHN OH ON .v. N - O O N ON ON ON OH OH ON O OH O 9. .39.: OO ON w. O NH HH OH OH OH ON O O OH OH NN HH OH N! g: .0 ON w OH u O ON HN OH OH OH O O OO . O OH O OH .23.: OO ON w O NH HH ON NN OH ON OH OH OH OH OH HH OH OI unnaqu OO On Ow ON OH OH ON OH OH ON O ON ON ON ON O OH ax >OIOHN OO On w ON O ON OH OH OH ON OH OH ON ON OH OH ON OI NOOIHN OO On w OH O OH NO On OH OH OH OH HN OH HH O ON H! 33 «0 ON w u . OH ON ON ON ON OH HN OH OH OH O ON a: OOONHO NO OO.H v H H H H H H H H H H H H H H 4: OOOH HO O O O O O O O O O O O O O O accuse-O- n: NOE HOE O: as O: Nap Hep N: Oh NO: HO: NOB Huh Om OO >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0O >0x >01 >0$ >0 >0 >0 .. n O O O O + H3: H3: “5 15 .8 Oz.— :03 . OOHHB . . O 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 OOO OHO OHO NHO OOO mam OO O‘ OO am“ am” «O mO ms HO O H 0. HO: H “OHOO. :oHuucsu OOHuf’uUU‘ COMuUSUOHG “Ono O’HUOOHQO .. .95an .33.: SOHHH> OOH-£33. :H .3336: 530.68.. 98.5.1.” 03.9 €56 O N. . O - u - - - O O - O O O o OI: «0OOOO ON O w - NH - - n u . O OH - OH O O . OOO OOOOOO ON O Aw . u - - u u n O O - - O O a OI: OOOOOO ON O w OH OH O - u u .. n u u .. .. o u 9. .53.:— ON O N. OH - O - - u - u u u - - - n .0. OOOOOO ON O w - - - - - - - - - - - - - - .O. OOOOO: ON O w n u - ON NN - - - OH OH O O OH O O: OOOOO: NN O W ON - - - - u - OH - u .. - n u 9. g HN O m. - - - - - - - OH - - - - - - .O. OOOOO: ON O N. ON . - u u - - - c - O - n - Ox OOOOOO OH O _w - - - - - O - - - N - N O O .0. OOOOOO OH O N O - - .. . OH NH - OH O - O O O 9. >95: OH O _w O - - n n O OH - . O O - u O HO. O0OOO: OH O .w OH - - - u u - - u - - O u O HO. manna: OH O N. ON OH O - . NH NH - NH O O OH NH NH Ox OOOOO: OH OH w O OH OH - u - n O - OH OH - u n O: OOOOOO OH OH NO O - O u . ON O - OH O u - u N O: OOOOOO NH OH N. O NH OH . - - OH NN O NH ON NH OH HH Ox OOOOOO HH ON w. s - N O O OH OH O O NH ON OH OH OH OI OOOOOO OH ON w O - O O N ON ON ON OH OH ON O OH O 0. 2.: OO ON w O NH HH OH OH OH ON O O OH OH NN HH OH O: OuOuOO OO ON w. OH - O ON HN OH OH OH O O OO .O OH O O: OOOOOO OO ON N. O NH HH ON NN OH ON OH OH OH OH OH HH OH O! 35.: OO OO w. ON OH OH ON OH OH ON O ON ON ON ON O OH 9. >88. OO OO w. ON O ON OH OH OH ON OH OH ON ON OH OH ON a: OOOOOO OO OO .w OH O OH NO OO OH OH OH OH HN OH HH O ON 0. .393... OO ON w - - OH ON ON ON ON OH HN OO OH OH O ON 6. 859. NO OO.H v H H H H H H H H H H H H H H O: OOOO HO O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Ono-soon: O: NO; HOO O: as O: Nye HOO O: OO NO: HO: Nap Huh OO OO >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >0x >0O >0‘ >0x >0 >0 >0 n .. + + O + O .3: 5: 5: .3: .a max OOHO . OOHc—H . . O 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 OOO OHO OHO NHO 44‘ mam OO OO O: Om“ Om” «O m« mg HO O H 0. .4: H "OHOO. OOHOOOOO OoHOHOHOOO OoHOuaooOO menu osHquOOO .. 359-3 53.: 8.23 {SSH-«Op OH 33333 c2638.. 85.....HO OHO-O. 67 .3338 .838 .O «Hair? .HO .38. .8 Eon-H33... No coins-HO... OOO. 000a I 3 >338 OO OOH I an .3893 OO 03 I a "was an 0 I 000.0N 8O.OI 000.OI I I 000.HHI 000.OI 000.0HI 000.OHI 00O.OI 000.0HI 000.0HI 00O.OI 000.OI 08 >m40.HxH0 NO 0 I I I I 08 OOO I I I I I I I I I 08 EDP—LO do 0 I I I I I I 000I 0OOI 00OI I I 08I 000I 00OI 00OI 08 5.8.50 0O 0 I I I I 0OH.HI 0Oo.HI I I I 0OOI 00OI OOO.HI 0Oo.HI 0OOI 8OI a 32:15 90 0 III 02.3 000.0 02. N I I I I I I I I I I I a .5300 00 000a .vu 000.0 I 00O.H I I I I I I I I I I I OK 3500 O0 000m W I I I I I I I I I I I I I I .5— ~38 ow 000N W I I I 000.2 000.3 I I I 000.0 000.... 000.0 000.0 000.0 OOO; .H. «300 O0 000... W 80.2 I I I I I I 000.0 I I I I I I a. £300 OO 000O .vI I I I I I I I 00N.O I I I I I I 9— 3x00 MO 0000 W. 80.3 I I I I I I I I I 00O.H I I I an .2300 NO 000O W I I I I I 000.N I I I 000.H I 000.H 000.0 0008 a: 06300 HO 0000 .VI 000.0 I I I I 000 O 000 O 00O.H 000.0 000.0 I 000.. 00O.n 00O.N OH- >800 00 000O W 08.5 000.2 I 000.0 I 000.0H 0008 000.0 03.2 000 O 02.3 000.3 000.0 00O.H a: 90900 On 008 .vI I 000.0H I I I 08.3 I 08.3 000.0H I 08.3 0O0.0 000.3 08; AI mum-HUD On 0000 v 000.0 0O0.0 000.0 I I 00v HH 000.0 000.0 000.: 30 O 0008 000.0H 000.: 80.0 .3 850 On 0 I N I I N I I I I OH I N I I I g BOON-H on 0 I OO I I ON I I I I OH I ON ON I I on us On 0 I OO I I On I I 0O I OH I 02 ON I I a lush on 0 I 000.3 000.2 000.3 I I 000.0 000.0 000.... 000.... 000 O 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 ION; gm On 0 I I I I ON ON I I I I I I I I I a 9.3qu NO 0 I I I I I I NH NH NH I I NH NH NH NH II 000% HO 0 I I I I on On I I I On On 0O 0O 0O. On an 088nm 0O 0 I I I I I I I I H I I I O I I s Rafi-2 ON 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Icon—Hg .HI NPH. Ht. .5 .HIH. .5 NE. H.rH. uh uh NEH Huh Nah. HPH. . . OO OO >0 >0 >0 >0 >0 >9. >0x >0x >2 O3. :93 >0 >0 >0 I I + + + + O 50 H30 H30 50 03:0 .0: a U U 0 = U U U U SI 34 O H4 N H < fir. “a” O¢ O¢ O< cud ON“ «0 m¢ m¢ #1 n H 0. .4: H 325. 0300.58 0.315004 :oHuuHHUOOO 0000 2,300.30 68528}; .O .38. 68 requirements as well as their contribution to farmer's income. Two levels of production technologies are iden- tified for each cropping pattern. One represents the pro- duction of crops under traditional technology with no use of modern/new inputs and the new technology with the use of new inputs such as fertilizers, insecticides/pesticides. Only for upland rice + corn f cassava cropping pattern did the data from the survey distinguish two levels of fertili- zation by the representative farms in the study area. When two or more crops are interplanted in a mixture, then the production activities are considered as single enterprise in terms of the mixture, rather than the indi- vidual crops in the mixture as a separate enterprise. This method saves us from the problem of allocation of join resources such as labor and land use for each crop. There are other problems associated with the use of mixed crop- ping as production activities in linear programming models as discussed by Crawford (1977). The activity unit is one hectare. The objective function coefficients (Cj) for the crop production activ- ities represent the costs of fertilizers, insecticides, and wages for hired labor for each unit of the activities. Negative signs are assigned because costs reduce the income of the farmers. The input-output for traditional and new technol- ogies are presented in Table 3.1. These coefficients are the amounts of various resources required to produce one 69 unit of production activities (e.g., to produce one hectare of mixed crop corn + upland rice f cassava). They are assigned positive signs because each activity used up the available resources or decreased the magnitude of restric- tions in the model. Coefficients with negative signs indi- cated the increase in the magnitude of the restrictions or resources associated with them. Both technological coefficients for the traditional and the new technologies were generated from the results of the survey in the study area. Some of the character- istics of the study area and the representative farms were presented in Chapter II. The elements of the study design were presented in Chapter I. The average input-output coefficients for each crop production activity in the model were determined from the grouping of farmers assumed to be similar in the planting time, rate of fertilizer applica- tions, monthly labor use, yield per hectare, seeding rate, plant population, and level of management. It was also assumed that the soil conditions were similar from farm to farm in the study area. Each coefficient in the model is the mean of the small sample observation from relatively similar farm situations. The differences of coefficients between traditional and the new technologies are mostly due to the differences in the rate of fertilizations and use of insecticides. The labor inputs are consequently higher per hectare for the new technology due to more labor use for fertilization, spraying, 7O weeding and harvesting due to a higher yield. In fact, as the rate of fertilization increased, the land required more intensive weeding by the family labor plus some exchange labor. The following table represents the average annual labor requirement under traditional and new technologies for selected crop enterprises. The adoption of the new technology increased the labor requirements in all cases. Table 3.2.--Labor Requirement per Hectare of Selected Crop Production Activities under Traditional and New Technologies. Labor Requirement per Hectare (mandays) Crop Enterprises* Traditional New Percent of Technology Technology Change C + ULR f CV 193 266 38 ULR + CV 224 251 12 C + CV 224 259 13 Source: Field Survey *For explanation of abbreviations, see Table Cl, Appendix C. (b) Labor and Animal Hiring Activities In the study area farmers needed to augment their family labor with hired labor. For land preparation oxen power is sometimes used to replace man labor. Labor and 71 animal hiring activities are presented in Column A15 to A30 in Table 3.3. Hired labor can be attained through various hiring arrangements including exchange labor, contract basis for specific farm operations or simply on a daily basis. Work paid per day was the most common system. The activity unit is one manday. Hiring animals for land preparation usually consists of an oxen team with one man. The unit of activity used here was the Animal Working Day (AWD) (a shorter period of time than a manday) which consists of about six hours per day for a team. The wage rates used were the wages prevailing in the study area during the period covered by the survey. Hired labor is renumerated in cash and/or in kind. For convenience of analysis the in kind payments were converted into money terms by multi- plying the quantity received by its existing price. For land preparation family labor, hired labor, and animals hired, after appropriate conversions, are assumed to be nearly perfect substitutes. For other types of activ- ities hired and family labor are assumed to be perfect substitutes. The hiring labor activities have negative coefficients in the family labor rows, indicating that an increase in one unit of hired labor relaxes the family labor constraints by one unit. The animal hiring activ- ities in the same way have negative coefficients of three, indicating that for land preparation an additional unit of animals hired will relax three units of family labor con- straints. The use of hired labor will decrease capital by 72 o M 9! >932 9H 0 w. HI 2 .5902 0N o v HI e... 009:... an o m HI ea 3502 ea c w. H I H! .538: ON 0 v H I H! .533: v... o m HI 9. »§: mu o .v. H I H! .358: «a 0 W H I H! .253: HN o Iv. H I H! :35: on 0 w H I 9. 5.83: 0H 0 v H I 9. 000x42 0H 0 M H I 9. >903: pH 0 W H I 9. 000.00. OH 0 w. H I H! 0093: OH o .v. H I 0. 0:53: 3 NH Iv. H I 0: .5330 NH 3 w HI 9. 2093.. «H 2 w H I H! .253: HH 2 w H I H! :05?— OH mm W H I 9. .283: 3 R w H I H! 00.08... no R w. H I a: 2:5...» 8 2 .v. H I H! 0093.. 3 8 w ,7 HI 9. 82.8.. no on w H I H I H! .893... 3 3 w 7 H I a: 000.30 3 2 v m I HI 6. 3530 No 8.2 I 8m? 8...? 087 0va 0va on? 00? ST 0...? 0va oomI comI 8? on? >02 .00 mum 0:: .SH. 2.... .2: EH: .2: 00.. 5:. 03 >02 .00 an: .9... a 3 .22 .2: .02 .22 .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: on: 3: on: R: 8: 2: cm: 3: 3: H}. 8: «H: 3: 2: 0H: OH: 2.30.30 .. 359.3 5.62. «03H; «33.38. :H 331.30: H232 a... non... ocHuEIIéA oHn-H. .< 5.3.2.2 .3 «Han... 00: 3:03-35:31 uo cog-.5393 a...» no... ddoommmmm o 9 cc :4 h 0 Q In '4 O VIVIVIVIVIvIvIVIVIVIVIvIvIVIvle OOOOOOOOOOOO vlvlvlvlvlvlvlvlvlvlvlvl H >97: 3 «H. H $34 3 2. H «fluid 3 as H §I=¢ 3 on H .573... 3 00 H Rania... 3 be H agin: g 00 H 52.3: 3 no H «5.3.. 3 .0 H Guild: 3 mm H .273... 3 «0 H uncle... 3 Ho H >973. g 3 H SOL... 3 an H humid.— 3 on H 0.3.3.. s an 02. a: .5de0 av omv 9. .5360 5 9.3 a.— rgoo 0' com m.— ..250 mv com 5. .2580 3 owe a: nflhxoo nv Omv a: 24380 «v cow 5. Uflnxoo Hv 8mH com 5. >200 3 com.— com ml 500 an 09.3 Omv A.— .3980 on oomH Sc 5. 85.00 pm OOmHI oomHI OOmHI oomHI ova omVI ova oomI OOmI omVI OmVI oomI oomI OOmI cva OmVI >9. .HOO mum 03‘ and ash. >5. a: at! nm... can. one >9. .HDO mum gt 4 .92 .92 .22 .22 .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3: .3... 3.. and a~¢ c~¢ hm: o~< m~< v~< n~< -< H~< ON: mH< QH¢ HIHG OH¢ mHt 0>H000nno .HuchUCOOIIIn In OHAIfi 74 its wage/payment rate. The availability of operating capital will determine the extent to which family labor will be substituted by the hired labor and the availability of the family labor itself. Labor and animal hiring activities have negative values on the Cj of the objective function. Each additional unit of labor or animal hired will reduce the value of objective function by the rate of wage/payment. Selling labor activities is not included because the representative farmers in the study area hire labor in the net. (c) Capital Borrowing Activities There are very limited formal loans in the study area both by government and the "Tani Makmur Project." The credit is a package deal consisting of fertilizers, insecticides, seeds, and some living allowance. Very few of the sample farmers joined this proqram. Borrowing activities were included in the model to evaluate the con- tribution (potentially) of credit facilities to farm income and enterprise organization. The capital borrowing will be specified on monthly terms with 18 percent interest rate annually. The activity unit will be in Rupiah (Rp). This activity is represented in the matrix Table 3.4 from Columns A52 to A63. 75 .o 59.2.2 .2. 03:... 00: 3:033:93... Ho :oHuaanmuo no... o w H a: 38:53 v: 88 w H m: 38:83 a: 88 w H 5. age: u: :8: w H .2 :28”. H: coo: w H a: 25:33 8 88 w H a: .38: E3 2. 83 .v. H a: .28: a: 2. 83. w H a: 38:33 2. ago. w H :: >ozu: at: a. 89.. w H .2 58:83 .2. coo: .w H a: ammo: 9:: c. :8: w H a: 85:83 2. o I HI H H H H H H H H H H H H .2 3a... a... o I H HI HI .2 .5960 :v o I H HI HI .2 .5560 3 o I H HI HI .2 :38: 3 c I H HI HI .2 :33 no a I H HI HI .2 53.3 3 c I H HI HI .2 :38 no 0 I H HI HI .2 .233 «v o I H HI HI a: 0:980 H. o I H HI HI .2 83.8 3 o I H HI HI .2 .6980 an o I H HI HI .2 3:30 on o I H HI .2 3.33 R s 3. o o o o o o o o o o o o :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I :H.I 8.58... $2.68 82.22:...3anzoamm<§u§u.§:2:§:flz§o:a>oz.bo::m82 a: m I I I I I I I I I I I Hug—.62 a“: «mu MN... «mu Hm“. ow“. aw“ ow“ hwy... aw“ mm“ ku Hm“ Hm.“ ku om“ om“ om” Hm” emu mm” cm” mm” «N 33330 .. 35:33 53:. 8.3:. 1.3.3.... 5 $3333 3.22.... :5 ucHsouuonIIéédHA-a 76 (d) Fertilizers, Insecticides, and Food Crop Buying Activities Fertilizers and insecticides are the major new inputs in the new technology and have been used by some farmers in the study area. Fertilizer buying activities are included in the model to allow farmers to purchase fertilizers. These buying activities are presented in the matrix table from Column A31 to A40 (Table 3.5). The activ- ity unit is one kilogram (kg). Fertilizer prices are subsidized by the government at Rp 80/kg at the farm level. Buying activities have negative coefficients in the objective function since buy- ing one unit of it will reduce the value of objective func- tion. Fertilizer buying activities also have negative coef- ficients on the fertilizer rows because they will increase the stock of fertilizer. Food crop buying activities for family consumption have positive coefficients in the food consumption rows since food crop buying increases the con- sumption constraints. Food crop buying activities have negative coefficients in the objective function since they will reduce the value of objective function by the price of food crop bought per unit. (e) Food Crop Consumption Activities The farm family consumption consists of grains (rice, corn) and root crops (cassava). The food crop con- sumption activities are shown in Table 3.5 from Column A41 77 .0 205:9. 5 H0 03:... 08 3333303.. .0 5333:... no... .vousg . OO.H—Hon H H H >96sz mm H 5.89.8 cm H ..H .mH ...H 5H TH 52:28 H: H H $5.50 2 H H 2:0950 S H H H 5.00.50 0... H H H 0: 32.80 :v 007 .2... .20 :0 :0 SI .2: 98:0 3 0:? 0: an: 29:0 H0 03 .2: 20:0 no 0:0 29:0 H0 9: >9. 98:0 3 H 8H 08H 0: 0: .50 20:0 0H 8H :m: :20 :::0 :n 3083033 0H DOOM 88 InH VIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII § 5250 Dawn an 3’8 gm NM zzgflm HM "Dun—am On T..- 8OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO o o o 0 5H... 8a.. 8+ ooH+ o o 0 SI SI 8HI SHI 8HI 8H1 SHI oomHI OQI 8| >8: :5. :3: 0... :mm om: cum: >380... 09:3 :m::§>m:oz:oo:uH:.. 2.... 0:0 82.50:"... 80.50.50 ml ONE a... m.“ a.“ w.“ m.” m.” a.” w.” m...” m...“ m...” e” .m m.” w.” w.” m.” w.” w... a“ H.” :3 00:30 .. 3.59:1. £9.02. 000:... m>umx0uma :H :oHuH0Huoc 0...:me cc: conga-5:00 no.5 000... .9335 mono woo... .wumuHHHquLII.m.n OHHHHHB. 78 to A43. The activity unit is one kilogram (kg). These activities have positive coefficients in the output rows of rice, corn, and cassava because they reduce the stocks of theSe crops. Soybeans produced are mostly for sale. (f) Crops Selling Activities and Seed Production Activities The crop produced is either to be consumed or sold. Minimum family consumption requirements will be satisfied first before any selling activities are undertaken. Soy- beans are sold without any constraints, since they are mostly produced for sale purposes. It is also assumed that selling activities are undertaken in the month of harvesting, so there will be no storage activities included in the model. Storage of food crops for the purpose of family consumption is allowed and storage for cassava could take place in the ground. Selling activities are represented in Table 3.5 from Column A44 to A47. The activity unit is one kilogram (kg). The prices of the products are the prevailing prices in the nearest market during the harvesting periods (Appendix E). The objective function coefficients are positive because selling added to the value of the objective function. The row coefficients of the output of the crops are also positive since selling activities reduce the stock of that crop. 79 (9) Transfer Activities These activities were shown in Table 3.4, Columns A64 to A74 represent activities which are used to pass sur- plus capital from one month to the next month during the year. Column A75 represents activity which is included as a device by which any capital surplus over requirements for operating capital is accumulated at the end of the crop year. This activity has a zero value in the objective function, a positive sign for the last month (July) oper- ating capital row and a negative sign on the amount of transfer row, which means increasing the capital accumula- tion at the end of the crop year. 3.4 Restrictions in the Model In this study farming is carried out under a number of constraints or restrictions, which include the avail- ability of land for cultivation, family labor, hired labor, operating capital, family consumption requirements, and the assumption of nonnegativity of activity levels. These con- straints are outlined in Table 3.1. Each type of these restrictions will be described below. (a) Land Restriction The amount of land for cultivation by the represen- tative farm is about 1.38 hectares, consisting of all dry- land for the upland farming system. Each family in this transmigration area received two hectares of unprepared land from the transmigration program, so most of them have idle 80 land not yet cultivated, possibly due to scarcity of family labor, other sources of labor or power, and capital. There was little evidence of land selling or rent- ing in the study area. So, no provision is made in the model for such activities. Only upland farming is considered in the model. Lowland farming is omitted because it was nearly absent in our sample farms, except in Central Lampung. Land is also assumed to be homogeneous in quality and fertility, soil structure and other conditions that affect the soil capa- bilities. The row unit is in hectares. (b) Labor Restrictions Family labor restrictions are specified on a monthly basis in the model. The focus is in the family labor restrictions in the critical month of farming operations, but noncritical months of labor requirements are also included in the model to provide a complete accounting for labor within the system. The row unit is mandays. The amount of family labor in each month was assumed to be equal to the number of days actually spent by the family members during each month. These figures were obtained , from the survey by the researcher in the study area and presented in Tables 2.6 through 2.9 in Chapter II. Family labor could be augmented by hired labor and animals hired especially for land preparation. The amount of labor and animals hired depend on the amount of labor 81 required relative to the family labor available, the amount of hired labor and animals available in relation to their wage rates/payments, and the amount of the operating capital available for hiring labor and animal power. The amount of animal power available was estimated from the number of adult cows and buffaloes usually used as sources of power for land preparation on the representative farms in the study area. The amount of hired labor available was assumed to be equal to the number of actual hired labor used in each month by the representative farm. The amount of operating capital was estimated from interviews at the beginning of the cropping year (August). The figure was also estimated from the actual expenditures obtained by the surveys conducted during the crop season. (c) Operating Capital Restrictions Difficulties were encountered in collecting the relevant data for estimation of the amount of operating capital available for farming activities. Consumption and production activities are difficult to separate in the small farmer's decision making process. In this study cash expenses of individual farm families are used as a proxy for the amount of the operating capital. The amount of cash expenses for the representative farm was set equal to the amount estimated to have been spent on hired labor, fertilizers, insecticides/pesticides, and animals hired during that crop year (1978/1979). These 82 were estimated from the survey conducted by the author as presented in Table 2.12 in Chapter II. The row unit is Rupiah (Rp). These operating capital constraints are also presented on the monthly basis. Transfer activities were used to pass surplus capital from one period to the next during the year. (d) Consumption Requirements It is assumed that the representative farm is moti- vated by the "first security rule," that is, the first priority is to produce their family food consumption requirements. Therefore, they need to produce the minimum amount of rice, corn, and cassava for the family consumption. For this purpose constraints were incorporated in the model to ensure the production of that minimum amount. The food consumption requirement for the family were derived from the results of a simple consumption survey undertaken by the author at the beginning of the crop year. (e) Nonnegativity Restriction One of the requirements for the use of linear pro- gramming in analyzing the small farm behavior is the non- negativity of the activities in the model. None of the activities in the model can be operated at negative levels. 3.5 Some Limitations of the Model Other activities and constraints could be included in the model. For example, nonfarm activities of family 83 members are excluded as are various types of the activities in the farming process. For example, some activities may require different types of labor. Other activities which might have been considered include additional level of fertilizations, different planting space for each crop, different planting times, and different harvesting methods. The number of activities in the model depends on the avail- ability of data and the objective of the study. Large and complex models are costly in terms of time, money, and other resources. It is not always certain that the benefits to be derived from additional activities in terms of precision for planning purposes are sufficient to justify the addi— tional costs. Complex models may be difficult to interpret in terms of tracing the logical causal relationship between a change in one variable and the resulting changes in pro- duction. The model developed in this study was kept as simple as possible but complete enough to reflect the farm situations in the study area. In this chapter we have described the linear pro- gramming model, its requirements, and the components to be employed. The results of the various applications of the models will be discussed in the following chapter. CHAPTER IV ANALYSIS OF THE RESULTS FROM THE LINEAR PROGRAMMING MODELS APPLICATIONS In Chapter III the structure of the linear program- ming in this study was described. This Chapter presents the analysis of the results of the applications of linear programming models for the representative farms. The analy— sis is focused on the changes in farm income, cropping patterns, resource use and productivity. Some criteria for economic efficiency measures in relation to the use of the new tech- nology are also presented. The base plan is described as the Optimal plan under the traditional technology1 with existing resource situations. Then more activities and coefficients reflecting the use of the new technology were added into the model and then the Optimal plan for the new technology with existing resources was determined. This plan is compared to the base plan in order to explain the likely effects of the ad0ption of the 1In the following, traditional technoloqy is inter- changeable with before the introduction of the new tech- nology, and new technology is interchangeable with after the introduction of the new technology. 84 85 new technology. The output of the linear programming analy- sis in each situation provided information on the value of objective function, the Optimal enterprise combination, the resOurces use and their respective marginal value producti- vities (MVPs), the nonoptimal activities with the cost associated with forcing each of them into the Optimal solution and the stability limits of the optimal plan (Stephen B. Harsh and J. Roy Black, 1975). On the first and second sections of this Chapter (Chapter IV) discussion emphasis is on the comparison of the optimal plan of the representative farm enterprises under the traditional and new technologies. The comparisons are based on the changes on farm income, resource use and productivity, average returns to resources as indications of the effects of the new technology in the three subregions of Lampung. In the third section, comparisons of the Optimal plan between the three subregions are presented to see the different effects of the new technology on the cropping patterns, resource use and crOp productivity, and average returns to limiting resources. In section four the effects of releasing family labor constraints are examined. In section five comparisons are made of the actual plan and the Optimal plan in each subregion to see the extent of adjust- ments by the representative farms. In the last section of this Chapter a summary of the results of the linear program- ming analysis is presented. 86 4.1 The Optimal Organization of the Represen- tative Farm Enterprise Under the Traditional Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung The validity of the Optimal solution depends on the realism of the assumptions made concerning prices, techno- logical coefficients and constraints. The Optimal linear programming solution may differ from farmers' experiences due to the limitations of the linear programming analysis which includes unknown omissions of some important factors. Thus some points of the farmer's behavior when making decisions may not be captured. The Optimal plan resulting from the present analysis under traditional technology with existing resources is presented in Table 4.1. The value of the objective function or total gross margin is equal to 167,383 Rupiah. Fixed cost does not include such items as depreciation of farm tools because in general fixed cost items are neligible in the study area. Thus total gross margin is the estimate of the net farm income. Average return estimates with reSpect to limiting resources such as land and labor are provided as follows: Gross margin = Total value of products - cash expenses Returns per hectare = Total gross margins - unpaid family labor - interest on owner's Operating capital (cash expenses) divided by the total area under culti- vation Return per manday of labor = Total gross margin - inter- est on owner's Operating capital (cash expenses) divided by the total labor used. 87 Table 4.l.--Optimal Plan, Gross Margin, Resource Use and Average Returns Under Traditional and New Tech— nologies with Existing Resources of the Repre- sentative Farm in North Lampung, Indonesia. Item* Unit Activity Level 1. C + ULR f CV (NT) HA 0.246 2. ULR 1‘ CV (NT) HA 0.195 3. Ulr - SB (NT) HA 0.682 4. CV (TT) HA 0.136 Total Land HA 1.259 Total Gross Margin RP 167,383 Family Labor Manday 188 Hired Labor Manday 33 Total Labor Manday 221 Animal Hired AWD 2.5 Operating Capital RP 20,500 Return/Hectare RP 55,526 Return/Manday of Labor RP 741 Source: Computed *For explanation of the abbreviations Appendix C. see Table C.l, 88 The most critical problem is the valuation of family labor, since the family labor input is the largest portion. Using the existing hired labor wage rates as an estimate of the Opportunity cost of family labor may be too high, since employment Opportunities outside farm is small or lacking. Valuing the family labor at zero is unrealistic, since family labor is limiting in the peak seasons. It is also true there is a slack season for family labor use. Even in the slack seasons the value of family labor may not zero, at least the value of family labor in this season is equal to the value of leisure time, which is believed to have positive value for the farmers themselves. Based on the labor situations in the study area where there are no land- less farmers and by the researcher's judgment, it is likely that the family labOr valued at the existing hired labor wage rate is relevant. This is overvalued labor in a non peak season months, but in fact, wage rates are very stable from season to season and without Government regulation on the minimum wage rates that affected the study area. The second problem is to assign the correct value to the cost of borrowing capital or the opportunity cost of own capital. This problem is not as crucial as valuing family labor since cash exPenses are only small portion of total expenses and are usually formal and informal interest rates. In the study area according to the results of the interviews, the farmers are not familiar with borrowing from moneylenders, family or friends, which is somewhat surprising. 89 A formal source of credit is from the ”BIMAS" program with 18 percent interest on loans in the form of fertilizers, insecticides, and a small amount of cash for cost of living if farmers join the prOgram. This interest rate has been, in fact, subsidized by the Government, because inflation rate was 25 percent in 1979. By assuming that the govern- ment of Indonesia will continue this BIMAS program loan to the small farmers, the 18 percent interest rate may be rele- vant to be used as a cost of borrowing or lending for the study area. This is not a realistic interest rate, since in real terms it is -7 percent with the rate of inflation at 25 percent. The representative farmers in the study area are not familiar with institutional borrowing or lending. But even if the level of interest rate is under valued, it would not change the results of the analysis since cash borrowing is negligible or completely absent and cash Operating expenditure is only a small portion of the total cost. Based on the above considerations, interest on bor- rowing and lending capital will be valued at 18 percent annually. The optimal plan under the traditional technology for Tatakarya village in North Lampung is presented in Table 4.1. The Optimal plan included all crops (upland rice, corn, soybeans, and cassava) and utilized almost all of the available land for cultivation. In the optimal plan mixed crOpping covered about 90 percent of the total cultivated area and single or pure stands covered only 10 percent. 90 In these instances cassava was the only crop in a pure stand in the optimal plan. Within the mixed cropping, three crop mixture of corn, upland rice and cassava covered 26.5 percent, and the two crop mixtures of upland rice and cassava covered 19.5 percent, and mixture of upland rice and soybeans covered 54 percent (the largest share) of the cultivated land area. Soybeans are grown in the study area as a cash crOp and not for direct consumption by the family farms. Not all the crop mixtures grown by the representative farm in the study area, were included in the optimal plan. Examples are a mixture of corn, upland rice and soybeans, and three crOps of soybeans in sequence (three crops of soy- bean in one crOp year). They are not competitive enough to be included in the optimal plan, e.g., three soybean crOps in sequence is not included in the otpimal plan due to its very intensive labor requirements. The total labor use in the optimal plan is 221 mandays which is made of 188 mandays of family labor and 33 mandays of hired labor. This does not include 2.5 animal working days which is equivalent to about 7.5 mandays of man labor for land preparation. Very limited Operating capital was used consisting of payments for hired labor and animal hired cost at about Rp20,500. This Operating capital is supplied from the initial funds available in the beginning of the cr0p year and the sales of surplus product beyond family con- sumption requirements. 91 The marginal value products (MVPs) are presented in Table 4.2 which is the shadow prices of resources within the constraints in the linear programming model. In this case the marginal value product of disposal activities is defined as the increase in the value of total output that is obtained from the use of additional units of the resource with all other inputs held constant. This condition may not met in the linear programming framework, because technologi- cal coefficients for activities are assumed to be at a fixed ratio to one another. So, the increase in one unit of only one input will require the increase in other inputs in order to keep the ratio or coefficient fixed. Although with this deficiency, marginal value product can give information on the most likely resources to be expanded in order to increase the value of the objective function or farm income. The marginal value product of a resource is constant over the Specific range and the solution holds until other resources become limiting. At that point another enterprise organiza- tion becomes Optimal and the marginal product of the resources change. The marginal value products indicate the productivity of resources on the farm. They indicate the amount of total gross margins of the farm products that could be increased by the utilization of the additional one unit of that resources. So they give information about the possible gains or losses in income which are possible through the acquisition of that scarce resource. The marginal value 92 Table 4.2.--Margina1 Value Products of Land, Family Labor, Operating Capital (MVPs) on the Optimal Plan Under Traditional Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung. Resource Unit MVPs (RP) 1. Land 0 2. Family Labor in August HA 0 3. Family Labor in September Manday 377 4. Family Labor in October Manday 6,922 5. Family Labor in November Manday 6. Family Labor in December Manday 7. Family Labor in January Manday 0 8. Family Labor in February Manday 0 9. Family Labor in March Manday 0 10. Family Labor in April Manday 0 11. Family Labor in May Manday 0 12. Family Labor in June Manday 0 13. Family Labor in July Manday 0 14. Operating Capital in August RP 6.8 15. Operating Capital in September RP 0 16. Operating Capital in October RP 0 17. Operating Capital in November RP O 18. Operating Capital in December RP 0 19. Operating Capital in January RP 0 20. Operating Capital in February RP 0 21. Operating Capital in March RP 0 22. Operating Capital in April RP 0 23. Operating Capital in May RP O 24. Operating Capital in June RP 0 25. Operating Capital in July RP 0 Source: Computed. 93 products of slack resources are zero and positive for the limiting factors or constraint resources. A higher a marginal value product of a resource indicates scarcity of that resOurce. The more limiting that resource the higher its marginal value product. So to be meaningful it should be compared to the cost of its acquisition or to its marginal factor cost. It is profitable to acquire an additional unit of resources if its acquisition cost is less than its mar- ginal value product. So maximum income can be obtained only if all marginal value products of all resources are equal to their marginal factor costs. Family labor was limiting for crOp production in September and October. These months correspond to the peak periods of land preparation and planting seasons. An addi— tional unit of labor in these months will increase farm income by the amount indicated by their respective marginal value products. The marginal value product of family labor is highest in October indicating that family labor was the most constraining in this month. The marginal value product of family labor in October is substantially higher than the prevailing wage rate. Family income could be increased if the family members are willing to work extra hours or days during this month or had the funds available for hiring labor (assuming hired labor is available). This high mar- ginal value product of labor also indicates that the farmers could afford to pay a much higher wage than the prevailing wage rate in order to attract more hired labor in this peak 94 season. In the month of September the marginal value product of labor is lower than the marginal factor cost of hired labor. Hence it would be unprofitable to hire more labor during this month. The marginal value product of Operating capital in August is 680 percent. Thus Operating capital in August is also a constraint in crOp production. In this month the marginal value product of Operating capital was much higher than its marginal factor cost of 18 percent. Hence farm income can be increased if more operating capital was made available. This may imply the need for short term credit to relax that Operating capital constraint which would permit purchase of more fertilizers and insecticides. In the following months the operating capital marginal value pro- ducts have zero values, since there is a slack of Operating capital during these months. Operating capital can be supplied after August from the sale of crOp products such as cassava in September, soybeans in February, corn in March, and rice in May. This source of funds for operating capital is more than enough to 00pe with the operational cash costs of cr0p production. The only credit they need is at the beginning of the farming operating which is used as cash expenses for land preparation. The amount needed is also very limited at about Rp9000 or equivalent to U.S. $15. This initial operating capital is usually also made available by the farmers them- selves, since there is no formal or informal credit available 95 for the farmers in the study area. This Operating capital can be obtained by working outside their farm for wage or from the previous product sales. So, it seems that credit is not a limiting factor in the context of traditional tech- nology for the representative farmer in the study area when they practiced mixed crOpping. This traditional mixed crOpping system is without additional new or modern inputs. The output of the linear programming routine also provided information on the activities excluded from the Optimal plan. They are excluded from the Optimal plan because they are the least profitable enterprises. The cost of forcing those excluded enterprises into the Optimal solution indicates how much the value of the objective function would be decreased (income penalty) if one unit of that enterprise was forced into the optimal plan. So it reveals the competitive position of that enterprise. The higher the cost or loss in income, the lower the competitive position of that enterprise and vice versa. The lower the cost of forcing that activity into the Optimal solution, the greater the potential to enter the Optimal plan if one or more of the contraints is relaxed. Low productivity of traditional farming is con- sidered the major constraint for increasing food crOp pro- duction and the income of the farmer in the study area. Without the introduction and application of the new inputs or new methods of production it is hardly possible that both production and income of small farmers can be improved. 96 The introduction of the new technology is believed to be the basis for improving the small farmers' conditions in the study area. But it will not guarantee this, unless supporting services are available in the right place and at the right time at the farm level, such as extension services, new agricultural inputs which are profitable, and transportation and marketing services. The following section of this Chapter will examine the changes in the cropping patterns, farm income, resource use and their productivities after the introduction of the new technology on the representative farm in the study area. 4.2. The Effects of the New Technology with Existing Resources in North Lampung The comparison between Optimum organization of the representative farm before and after the introduction of the new technology will provide information on the likely effects of the new technology. This comparison is presented in the following Table 4.3. The total gross income of the representative farm is Rp283,089 which represents an increase of about 69 percent over the total gross income of the optimum farm plan under the traditional technology. So, it indicates that farmers who are income or profit maximizers could improve their gross income by approximately 69 percent through the adoption of the new technology. The Optimum plan after the introduc- tion of the new technology with the existing resource levels included 0.214 hectares crop mixture of corn + upland rice f 97 Table 4.3.--A Comparison of the Optimum Farm Organization of the Representative Farm Under Traditional and New.Technologies with Existing Resources in North Lampung. Before After Introduc- Introduc— tion of tion of new Tech— New Tech- Change Item* Unit nology nology Percent 1. c + ULR f cv (TT) HA 0.246 0.214 ) ) 190 2. C + ULR f CV (NT) HA - 0.500 ) 3. ULR + CV (TT) HA 0.195 - -100 4. ULR - SB (TT) HA 0.682 - ) -21 5. ULR - SB (NT) HA - 0.536 ) 6. CV (TT) HA 0.136 - -100 Land HA 1.259 1.250 0 Total Gross Margin Rp 167,383 283,089 69 Family Labor Manday 188 232 23 Hired Labor Manday 33 33 0 Total Labor Manday 221 265 20 Animal Hired AWD 2.5 9.5 280 Operating Capital Rp 20,500 39,025 90 Source: Computed. *For explanation of abbreviations see Table C.l, Appendix C. 98 casava under the traditional technology and 0.500 hectares of the same crop mixture under the new technology. It should be noted that after the introduction of the new tech- nolOgy into mixed cr0p systems of upland rice + corn f casava in the Optimal farm plan, there still existed two levels of technology. One was without use of new inputs (traditional) and one was with use of new inputs such as fertilizers, insecticide, and improved seeds (new technology), which covered 0.214 hectares and 0.500 hectares respectively. This means that this crOp mixture is competitive both under traditional and under the new technologies in the conditions in the study area. This cr0p mixture is the most pOpular crOpping pattern practiced by the farmers both in terms of acreage devoted to it and the number of farmers practicing it (see Table 2.1 and Table 2.2 in Chapter II). The second crOp mixture under the new technology in the optimal plan is upland rice - soybeans with use of new inputs of fertili- zers and insecticide. This crOp mixture is the most competi- tive under the new technology which covered 0.536 hectates. After the introduction of the new technology, the cropping pattern is less diversified and all crOpping systems are in mixtures. None of the sole crOps appeared in the Optimal plan under the new technology. This means that the mixed crOpping pattern is more competitive than the sole crOpping pattern. The crOpping pattern of mixed crops of upland rice + cassava is eliminated in the Optimal plan 'under the new technology. Sole crOp of cassava is also 99 eliminated in the Optimal plan after the introduction of the new technology. The costs of forcing nonoptimal crop production activities into the Optimal solution (Table 4.4) revealed that mixed crop of upland rice + corn f cassava with the use of animal power for land preparation (classified as traditional technology) has the highest potential to enter the Optimal plan. So, this cropping pattern with the use of animal power for land preparation has the lowest cost or income penalty when entered into the optimal plan under the new technology if one or more restrictions were relaxed. The adoption of the new technology also changes the allocation of resources among crops or among crOp mixtures. For the mixed crOp of corn + upland rice f cassava in the Optimal plan under new technology, land devoted is 0.714 hectares from 0.246 hectares before the introduction of the new technology. There is an increase of 190 percent of land devoted to this mixed cropping pattern. For mixed cr0p of upland rice - soybeans there is a decrease in land devoted to it after the introduction of the new technology from 0.682 hectares before the introduction of the new technology to 0.536 hectares, a decrease of 21 percent. Crop mixture of upland rice + cassava was eliminated after the introduction of the new technology. There is no significant change in the total land devoted or under cultivation after the intro- duction of the new technology compared with the optimal plan before the introduction of the new technology. 100 Table 4.4.--Cost of Forcing in NonOptimal Activities (Result of the Linear Programming Analysis) Under the New Technology with Existing Resources of the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Cost of Forcing in Into Nonoptimal Activities* Optimal Plan (RP) l. C + ULR 1‘ CV (TT2) 8477** 2. C + ULR 1‘ CV (NTl) 59216 3. ULR f CV (TT) 101430 4. ULR f CV (NT) 21891 5. C + CV (TT2) 202163 6. C + CV (NT) 20216 7. ULR - SB (TT) 17934 8. CV (TTl) 74146 9. CV (TT2) 131800 Source: Computed. * For explanation of abbreviations see Table C.l, Appendix C. **The lowest cost (income penalty) of forcing in nonoptimal activities into the Optimal plan. 101 After the introduction of the new technology there are increases in use of family labor, hired labor, and animal draft power. Family labor use increases from 188 mandays to 232 mandays or an increase of about 23 percent. There is no change in the use hired labor after the introduction the new technology. Animal draft use increases from 2.5 animal working days to 9.5 animal working days. Animal draft is only used for land preparation in the beginning of the cropping season. Hired labor is assumed as a substitute for family labor. Hired labor is used for land preparation, planting, weeding, and harvesting. Operating capital increases from Rp20,500 before the introduction of the new technology to Rp39,025 after the introduction of the new technology. The increase in the cash expenses is for payment of hired labor, animals hired and for the purchases of the new inputs such as fertilizers and insecticides. The average return to the factors of production also increases after the introduction of the new technology. The average return per hectare of land before the introduction of the new technology was Rp55,526. The return increased to Rp132,639 after the introduction of the new technology, an increase of about 139 percent. The average return to family labor per manday after the introduction of the new technology was Rp1,04l, an increase of about 40 percent from the traditional technology. 102 There is a remarkable increase in the use of Oper- ating capital of about 90 percent after the introduction of the new technology. The marginal value products of the resources under the new technology and under the traditional one are compared in Table 4.5. The marginal value product of land under both technologies is zero, i.e., land is idle. Family labor is constraining in September and October before the introduction of the new technology and family labor is limiting in Novem— ber and January after the introduction of the new technology. So, it seems that there is a shift in family labor as limiting factor during land preparation under the traditional technology into the weeding season under the new technology. This may be due to more heavy weeds under the new technology. The marginal value product of family labor is highest in October under the traditional technology during the land preparation and planting seasons. The marginal value product of family labor is highest in November and January under the new technology and is much higher than the prevailing wage rates in the two months. Farmers can afford to hire more labor at a much higher wage. These factors emphasize the need for fund availability to hire more labor to break the labor constraint during these two months with the assumption that hired labor supply is not constraint. Operating capital is the only limiting in August during the land preparation and just a month before cassava harvesting. By limiting the amount of capital to be borrowed in each month (for example 103 Table 4.5.--A Comparison of Marginal Value Products (MVPs) of Land, Family Labor, and Operating Capital on the Optimal Plan Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources of the Representative Farms in North Lampung. Marginal Value Product Resource Unit Traditional New Technology Technology 1. Land HA 0 O 2. Family Labor in August Manday 0 O 3. Family Labor in September Manday 377 0 4. Family Labor in October Manday 6922 O 5. Family Labor in November Manday 0 100 6. Family Labor in December Manday 0 0 7. Family Labor in January Manday O 24 8. Family Labor in February Manday 0 0 9. Family Labor in March Manday 0 0 10. Family Labor in April Manday 0 0 11. Family Labor in May Manday 0 0 12. Family Labor in June Manday 0 0 13. Family Labor in July Manday 0 0 14. Operating Capital in August RP 6.8 6.8 15. Operating Capital in Sept. RP 0 0 16. Operating Capital in Oct. RP 0 0 17. Operating Capital in Nov. RP 0 0 18. Operating Capital in Dec. RP 0 0 19. Operating Capital in Jan. RP 0 0 20. Operating Capital in Feb. RP 0 O 21. Operating Capital in March RP 0 0 22. Operating Capital in April RP O 0 23. Operating Capital in May RP 0 O 24. Operating Capital in June RP 0 0 25. Operating Capital in July RP O 0 Source: Computed. 104 in August the limited amount can be borrowed is set at 6000 Rupiah (see Table 3.1 for other months limited borrowing) the linear programming analysis shows that the marginal value product of operating capital is zero except for August which is 680 percent. It is very high and it is a very crucial time for the farmers to have this fund available at the beginning of the farming operation, i.e., for land preparation. By conducting sensitivity analysis, by changing the limited borrowing in August from 6000 Rupiah to 9000 Rupiah, the analysis shows that the marginal value product of cash operating capital in August becomes zero. The critical fund- ing required in August for land preparation is well known by the farmers in the study area from their experience. According to the result of the interview with the farmers in August 1979 at the beginning of land preparation, the representative farm has 9000 Rupiah cash already available on hand. This amount is used as the limited amount of borrowed capital in the sensitivity analysis and the results shows that the marginal value product of cash Operating capital in August becomes zero. This may imply that there is enough cash available by the farmer without borrowing to cover the cash expenses even under the new technology. The cash for expenses can be obtained by the farmer himself by working off of his farm for wages or from the previous sales of his crOps. 105 The total cash expenditure increases dramatically with the introduction of the new technology by 90 percent from 20500 Rupiah to 39025 Rupiah. This increase in cash expenses is for payment of additional hired labor, animals hired and for purchases of the new inputs such as fertilizers and insecticides. The increase of the cash expenses after the ad0ption of the new technology is usually covered by the farmer by selling his crop products after harvest such as cassava in September, soybean in February, corn in March, and rice in May. This procedure is possible since the representative farmer has been familiar with the mixed crOpping systems. In addition, farmers can work off of their farm for wages before the land preparation. Operating capital for the representative farmer is not critical in most of the months. There is a very significant increase in animal draft use from 2.5 animal working days under the traditional tech- nology to 9.5 animal working days under the new technology. The supply of hired labor is also limited since there are no landless farmers in the study area. The major source of hired labor is the newly arrived transmigrants and their family members. They have to sacrifice some of their labor for wages in order to sustain living for family at least in first season of their arrival. Seasonal labor from Java is also limited due to relatively high transportation costs compared to their expected income. Social and cultural factors also limit the mobility of labor from Java to Lampung. 106 The study conducted by Gloria Davis (1979) in Lampung show that the longer the transmigrants have settled in the area, the larger the area of the available unprepared land (two hectares fOr each family) that was brought into pro- duction of food crOps as well as perennial crOps. This means that the number of family labor hired out becomes less and less, so that the supply of hired labor becomes a limiting factor. Other sources of power need to be considered to release part of these labor constraints. Investment in these sources of power such as cows and/or buffaloes, and tractors is required. For this purpose medium to long term credit may be needed by the representative farmers in the study area since they do not have enough savings due to the low income. According to the results of the interviews with the representative farms in North Lampung, this need was expressed. The Optimal plans after the introduction of the new technology for the representative farms in Central and South Lampung are presented in Table 4.6 and Table 4.7 respectively. Similar analysis could be done for each region as has been done for North Lampung (represented by Tatakarya village). The complete analysis will not be repeated here as for North Lampung. Only some differences will be discussed. For the representative farm of Central Lampung not only upland cr0p production activities but also lowland rice or irrigated rice production activities are included in the 107 Table 4.6.--Optimum Organization of the Representative Farm Under the New Technology with Existing Resource LeVels in Central Lampung. Item* Unit Adiluih and Bulusari 1. C + ULR f CV (NT) HA 0.262 2. ULR f CV (TT) HA 0.240 3. C + SB f CV (NT) HA 0.518 4. LLR (NT) HA 0.240 Total Land HA 1.260 Total Gross Margin RP 182,238 Family Labor Manday 219 Hired Labor Manday 71 Total Labor Manday 290 Animal Hired AWD 12.8 Operating Capital RP 70,000 Return/Hectare RP 52,074 Return/Manday of Labor RP 585 Source: Computed. *For explanation of the abbreviations see Table C.l, Appendix C. 108 Table 4.7.--Optimum Organization of the Representative Farm After the Introduction of the New Technology with Existing Resource Levels in South Lampung. Item* Unit Pugung Raharja 1. ULR - SB/CV HA 0.325 2. SB - SB - SB/CV HA 0.321 3. ULR + C - SB/CV HA 0.454 Total Land HA 1.100 Total Gross Margin RP 192,970 Family Labor Manday 257 Hired Labor Manday 5 Total Labor Manday 262 Operating Capital RP 7,500 Return/Hectare RP 63,223 Return/Manday of Labor RP 731 Source: Computed. *For explanation of the abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 109 linear programming model. Total irrigated rice fields covered 0.24 hectares for the representative farm. For this irrigated rice, use of fertilizers, insecticides, and improved seeds has been far in advance of the dryland crop farming. On the average the use of fertilizers is the highest in the Central part of the Lampung subregion. Also of hired labor is the highest in Central Lampung compared to the other subregions of Lampung. The optimum plan for Pugung Raharja (representing South Lampung subregion) after the introduction of the new technology is presented in Table 4.7. Fertilizer, the main input for the new technology, is not yet familiar to the representative farmer in this subregion. They did not use fertilizer in their crOp cultivation. The only modern input they have used is insecticides for soybean crop protection. Soybeans are the major cash crOp for the representative farmer in this area. For North and Central Lampung rice and cassava are the major crOps for the representative farm (Table 4.9). Component and the level of the technology on the optimal plans after the introduction of the new technology in the three subregions of Lampung is presented in Table 4.8. The comparison is in terms of the level of fertilizers, insecticides, and use of improved or local seeds. Land preparation by manual labor and/or by the use of animal draft power is still considered to be traditional technology. The table shows that the highest level of fertilizers on 110 Table 4.8.--Comparison of the Level of Technology on Optimal Plans for the Representative Farms in the Three Subregions of Lampung. Tatakarya Adiluih and Pugung Bulusari Raharja Item (N.Lampung) (C.Lampung) (S.Lampung) l. Fertilizers/Hectare 112.8 kg 140.5 kg — 2. Insecticides/Hectare 2 liters 2 liters 3.3 liters 3. Seed Variety Mixed Mixed Local 4. Land Preparation (M+A)** (M+A)** M *Mixed = Use of both local and improved seeds. **(M+A) = For land preparation by man labor and use of animal draft power. (M) = For land preparation use of man labor only. the Optimal plan after the introduction of the new technology is for Central Lampung and next to it is North Lampung, and none for South Lampung. This is due to the fact that the representative farm in South Lampung not yet used fertilizers. So, there is no crOp production activities with use of fertilizer in the linear programming model for South Lampung. The levels of fertilizers in the optimal plan after the introduction of the new technology are much lower than the recommended levels of fertilizers by "BIMAS" program or by l"TANI MAKMUR PROJECT." Both of these agencies recommend fertilizer use of 200 KG/hectare. The level of insecticide use is similar to the project recommendations of about 2 liters per hectare. 111 4.3. Comparison of Optimal Plan Under the New Technology and Existing Resource Levels Between the Three Subregions of Lampung In the previous sections of this Chapter the results of the applications of the Linear Programming model for the representative farms in North Lampung has been presented. The presentation included the analysis of the Optimal plan under traditional technology and the analysis of the effects of the new technology by comparing the base plan with the optimal plan under the new technology. In analyzing the effects of the new technology emphasis was given to the changes in farm income, resource use and their productivities and crOp enterprise combinations. In this section compari- sons of the Optimal plan under new technology and existing resource levels between the three subregions of Lampung will be presented. The level of technology, crOpping patterns, and the level of crOp productivities will be compared between the three subregions in Table 4.9 and Table 4.10. The dominant crOpping patterns in North Lampung are mixed cropping of corn + upland rice f cassava and mixed cropping of upland rice - soybeans. For Central Lampung the dominant cropping pattern is the mixed crOpping of corn + soybean i cassava. In South Lampung the dominant crOpping pattern is mixed crOpping of corn + upland rice - soybeans. From the two tables it can be seen that the major crops for North and Central Lampung are rice and cassava in terms of land devoted to this crops and in terms of total crOp pro- duction. {For South Lampung the dominant crOp is soybeans 112 Table 4.9.--Comparis0n of CrOpping Patterns of the Optimal Plans Under the New Technology and Existing Resources for the Representative Farms of the Three Subregions of Lampung. . Sub Region Item Unit North Central South CrOpping Pattern:* l. ULR + C f CV (NT) HA 0.500 0.262 - 2. ULR + C { CV (TT) HA 0.214 — - 3. ULR + C - SB/CV (NT) HA - - 0.454 4. ULR f CV (TT) HA - 0.240 - 5. ULR - SB (NT) HA 0.536 - 0.325 6. C % CV - SB (NT) HA - 0.518 - 7. SB - SB - SB/CV (NT) HA - - 0.321 8. LLR (NT) HA - 0.240 - Total Land HA 1.250 1,260 1.100 Total CrOp Production: Rice KG 1,607 1,827 624 Corn KG 407 469 228 Soybean KG 322 260 771 Cassava KG 9,714 7,649 3,015 Source: Computed. *Perennial crOpping pattern not included. For explanation of abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 113 in terms of land devoted to this crop and in terms of the value of the crop. The differences in crops and crOpping patterns may be attributed some to the differences in soil, rainfall, prices of agricultural products and marketing services available to the representative farms. For example, the cassava processing industry recently has been concentrated in Central Lampung and now is at over capacity (Nainy, 1979). This will encourage cassava production if the price of cassava is attractive to the farmers. Cassava not only is a staple crOp but also is a cash crOp for the representative farm in the study area. Lampung has been a major receiving area for transmigrants and has a very active cassava based industrial sector producing both starch for domestic con- sumption and pellet for export. Production grew rapidly from 300,000 tons of fresh roots in 1969/70 to 8000,000 tons by 1977 (Dixon, 1979). The following table shows the level of technology in the Optimal plan in terms of use of modern inputs such as fertilizers, insecticides, crOp productivities in the three subregions of Lampung. The highest level of fertilizer use is in Central Lampung and next to it is North Lampung. N0 fertilizer is used in South Lampung. The level of insecticide use is near the recommended level of 2 liters per hectare. From the comparisons made in this analysis there appears to be a comparative advantage in type of crOp pro- duced and the type of crOpping patterns to be used in 114 Table 4.10.--Comparison of Resource Use and Productivity on the Optimal Plan Under New Technology with Existing Resources of the Representative Farms in the Three Subregions of Lampung. Resource Use and Produc- tivity in Subregions Item Unit North Central South 1. Total Land HA 1.25 1.26 1.10 2. Fertilizers Use/Hectare KG 112.5 140.5 0 3. Insecticides/Hectare Liter 2 2 3.3 4. Family Labor/Hectare Manday 195 175 234 5. Hired Labor/Hectare Manday 38 58 S 6. Animal Draft Hired/Hectare AWD 10 10 0 7. Total CrOp Production/HA* KG Rice KG 1285 1450 567 Corn KG 326 372 207 Soybean KG 258 206 612 Cassava KG 7771 6071 2741 Source: Computed. *Cr0p productivity per hectare is in various mixed crOpping patterns and not as a sole crop. 115 producing that crop for each subregions of Lampung (Table 4.11). North Lampung has a comparative advantage in pro- ducing cassava and upland rice in mixed cropping patterns of upland rice + corn f cassava and mixed cropping of upland rice - soybeans. Central Lampung has a comparative advantage of producing rice and cassava with cropping patterns in mixed cropping of corn % cassava - soybeans, upland rice + corn { cassava, upland rice f cassava, and low land rice (irrigated ricefield) as a sole crop. South Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing soybeans with cropping patterns consisting of triple crOpping of soybeans in sequence, and mixed cropping of upland rice + corn - soybean, upland rice - soybeans. On every crOpping pattern in South Lampung there is always a soybean crop in it. The compara- tive advantage is also indicated by the total cr0p pro- duction and per hectare basis of each crop produced by the representative farm in each subregion of Lampung (see Table 4.9 and Table 4.10). But it should born in mind that the analysis only covered a small area of upland farming in the study area and it may not represent other crOpping patterns such as for perennial crops, fruits and vegetables, lowland rice, and the highly mechanized large scale upland farming in Lampung. 4.4. The Effects of Releasing Family Labor Constraints on the Optimal Plan Under the New Technology As pointed out in the previous section, the marginal value product attached to family labor is high in November 116 .mcsmaon nusom u .H.m .masmsmn Hmuusou u .A.U .mqsmamn nunoz u .A.z«¢ .O xflocmmmd .H.O manna mom mcofiuma>onnnm on» no sowumcmamxo Mom: . 6005980 " mousom I I I I I I I I I I comm I Haze mHH .m I I I 0mm I I com I I 000 I I Haze >0\mm I 0 + «H0 .> comm I I ooaH I I I I I I I I Haze >0xmm I mm I mm .0 I oooo I I com I I com I I I I Haz. mm I >0 \ 0 .m I 0000 I I I I I I I I com I H993 >0 x «H0 .4 comm I I com I com I I I com I omHH H92. >0\mm I mg: .m I I comm I I I I I com I I om: Haas >0 I mg: + 0 .m I ooooH ooomH I I I I com com I oomH ommH Haze >0 x mHS + 0 .H .H.m ..H.0 .H.z .H.m .H.0 .H.z .H.m .H.0 .H.z .H.m .H.0 .H.z m>mmmmu cmonaom suoo mowm «ououumm mnemmouo Home mumuomm Hm: 00:000 mono .msamsmq mo mGOHOOHASm mouse may coozuom mmoHocnooa 302 0:0 H0009 mcuouumm mofimmouu moowum> mo moauw>wuosooum mono mo GOmHHmmSOOII.HH.¢ OHQMB 117 and January in the Optimal plan after the introduction of the new technology in North Lampung. So by increasing the availability of family labor during these months, farm incOme will increase. Family labor input can be increased by the family members by working more days and/or more hours in a day. Assuming the farm family members would consider an increase family labor input during these months, an attempt was made to analyse the economic effects of this family effort. It is hOped that the result of the analysis will also show the extent to which a family labor is a con- straint under the new technology. The number of mandays that the family could supply will be set equal to the number of mandays of family labor input in the peak season/month. Other resources, prices, and technological coefficients are assumed to be unchanged. The results of the analysis is presented in Table 4.12 through Table 4.14. For North Lampung (see Table 4.12) an increase in family labor input during the peak season (November and January), ceteris paribus, has an effect on the expansion of farm income. Total gross margin increased from Rp283,089 to Rp303,314, an increase of 7 percent. Family labor use increased from 232 mandays to 252 mandays, an increase of 9 percent. Hired labor use increased from 33 mandays to 35 mandays, an increase of 6 percent. Total labor input increased from 265 mandays to 287 mandays, an increase of 8 percent. 118 Table 4.12.--Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Existing Resource Levels and Increased Family Labor in North Lampung. . Existing Increased Change Item* ' Unit Resource Labor Percent l. C + ULR f CV (TT) HA 0.214 0.185 -13.5 2. C + ULR % CV (NT) HA 0.500 0.500 0 3. ULR - SB (NT) HA 0.536 0.583 9 4. CV (TT) HA - 0.112 Total Land HA 1.250 1.380 10 Total Gross Margin RP 283,089 303,314 7 Family Labor Manday 232 252 9 Hired Labor Manday 33 35 6 Total Labor Manday 265 287 8 Animal Draft AWD 9.5 9.5 0 Hired Operating Capital RP 39,025 39,975 2 Return/hectare RP 132,692 127,839 3 Return/Manday of RP 1,041 1,032 1 Labor Source: Computed. *For explanation of the abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 119 more family labor is used, there is the expected decrease in return to labor from Rp104l to Rp1032, indicating diminishing return to labor. There were no changes in animal draft hired after the labor constraint was relaxed. The relaxation of the labor constraint brought more land into production of food crOps and land became a limiting factor as shown by the shadow price of land at Rp88,99l. Returns per hectare decreased from Rp132,692 to Rp127,839, a decrease of 3 percent, indicating a diminishing return to land as more land was brought into production. Operating capital increased from Rp39,025 to Rp39,975, an increase of 2 percent. This increase in Operating capital was due to increase in hired labor input. There were also changes in the crOp enterprise com- bination. Sole cr0p of cassava entered the Optimal plan when the family labor constraint was relaxed. Land devoted to a crOp mixture of corn + upland rice f cassava decreased from 0.214 hectares to 0.185 hectares, a decrease of about 13.5 percent. Land devoted to a crop mixture of upland rice - soybeans increased from 0.536 hectares to 0.583 hectares, an increase of 9 percent. This increase in land devoted to this crOp mixture of upland rice - soybeans was at the expense of the decrease in land devoted to the crOp mixture of upland rice + corn { cassava. Also more land was brought into production as family labor became more available. The effects of increasing family labor in Adiluih and Bulusari villages (representing Central Lampung) is presented in 120 Table 4.13. Total gross margin increased from Rp182,238 to Rp195,658, an increase of 7 percent. Family labor use increased from 219 mandays to 235 mandays, an increase of 7 percent. Hired labor also increased from 71 mandays to 78 mandays, an increase of 10 percent. Total labor use increase from 290 mandays to 313 mandays, an increase of 8 percent. The increase in labor use had an effect on the decrease in returns to labor from Rp585 to Rp578, an indi- cation of diminishing return to labor. Operating capital increased from Rp70,000 to Rp81,300, an increase of 16 percent. The marginal value product of dryland was Rp178,954 and the marginal value product of wet- land/irrigated ricefield was Rp237,996, much higher for irrigated land. This may indicate that one of the strategies to increase farm income is to convert dry upland into irrigated land (assumed technically and economically feasible). Land becomes more limiting as more family labor is available. The Optimum farm organization became less diversified as family labor became available. The crOp enterprise mixture of upland rice f cassava is eliminated from the optimal plan as family labor became available in the peak season. More land was devoted to the cr0p mixture of corn + upland rice f cassava from 0.262 hectares to 0.574 hectares as more family labor became available. The effects of increasing family labor input in Pugung Raharja (represents South Lampung) are presented in Table 4.14. Total gross margin increased from Rp192,970 to 121 Table 4.13.--Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Increased Family Labor in Central Lampung. Existing Increased Change Item* Unit Resources Labor Percent l. C + ULR f CV (NT) HA 0.262 0.574 119 2. ULR f CV (TT) HA 0.240 - 3. C f CV - SB (TT) HA 0.518 0.446 14 4. LLR (NT) HA 0.240 0.240 0 Dry Land HA 1.02 1.02 0 Wet Land HA 0.24 0.24 0 Total Land HA 1.26 1.26 0 Total Gross Margin RP 182.238 195,658 7 Family Labor Manday 219 235 7 Hired Labor Manday 71 78 10 Total Labor Manday 290 313 8 Animal Draft AWD 12.8 15 17 Hired Operating Capital RP 70,000 81,300 16 Return/Hectare RP 52,074 55,076 6 Return/Manday of RP 585 578 -1 Labor Source: Computed. *For explanation of the abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 122 Rp195,692, an increase of 1.5 percent. Family labor use increased from 257 mandays to 268 mandays, an increase of 4 percent. The increase in gross margin was not so signi- ficant compared to increase in family labor input of 4 per- cent. It may not be worthwhile to increase family labor input into the farm by 4 percent if gross income increases only by 1.5 percent. Hired labor was eliminated after the family labor became available. Total labor input increased by 2 percent, all supplied by the family labor. As the labor input in- creased, the return to labor decreased, again indicating diminishing return to labor. Average return to labor de- decreased from Rp73l/manday to Rp7l7/manday. Operating capi- tal decreased from Rp7,500 to Rp5,000 due to no more use of hired labor, and there were no changes in the use of cash inputs such as for purchasing fertilizers and insecticides. It seems that the representative farm in South Lampung subregion has used its resources, e.g., labor, nearly Optimally in most traditional techniques. The only new input used by the representative farm was insecticides, with no use of other modern inputs such as fertilizers and improved seeds. So the strategy to increase food production and farm income is to introduce new productive and profitable inputs. Farmers must be shown a tangible fashion in readily comparable circumstances, the new production techniques. They must be shown the risk involved both in yield and price fluctuations. They must also be aware of the farmer expenditure constraints. 123 Table 4.14.-—Optima1 Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology with Increased Family Labor in South Lampung. I Existing Increased Change Item* Unit Resource Labor Percent 1. ULR - SB/CV HA 0.325 0.368 13 2. ULR + C - SB/CV HA 0.454 0.411 9 3. SB - SB - SB/CV HA 0.321 0.321 0 Total Land HA 1.100 1.100 0 Total Gross Margin RP 192,970 195,692 1.5 Family Labor Manday 257 268 4 Hired Labor Manday 5 0 -100 Total Labor Manday 262 268 2 Operating Capital RP 75,000 5,000 -33 Return/Hectare RP 63,223 62,420 -1 Return/Manday of RP 731 727 -0.5 Labor Source: Computed. *For explanation of abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 124 4.5 Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farms Under New Technology with Existing Resources Table 4.15 through Table 4.17 present the comparison of actual and optimal plans under the new technology and existing resources in the three subregions North, Central, and South Lampung. North Lampung (see Table 4.15) shows a significant difference between the actual/observed plan and the Optimal plan. Land devoted to the Optimal plan is smaller by about 9 percent, 1.38 hectares in the actual plan and 1.25 hectares in the Optimal plan. This may be due to the fact that in the actual plan more labor is used (255 mandays) compared with 232 mandays for the optimal plan. Cr0p enterprise combinations differ significantly and are less diversified under the Optimal plan. CrOp mix- tures of corn + cassava, and upland rice f cassava were eliminated in the Optimal plan. Sole crop of cassava also does not enter the optimal plan. There was a relatively very large increase in land devoted to crOp mixture of up- land rice - soybeans from 0.03 hectares in the actual plan to 0.536 hectares in the Optimal plan, an increase of 1777 percent. In North Lampung, total gross margin is higher by 43 percent in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan even though land cultivated is smaller. Return to labor is higher in the Optimal plan by 54 percent than in the actual plan. Return to land per hectare is very significantly higher in the Optimal plan, by 158 percent. 125 Table 4.15.--A Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in North Lampung. Actual Optimal Change Item* ’ Unit Plan Plan Percent 1. c + ULR % CV (TT) HA) 0.214) ) 0.620 ) 15 2. c + ULR { CV (NT) HA) 0.500) 3. ULR - SB (NT) HA 0.03 0.536 1777 4. ULR i CV (TT) HA 0.19 - -100 5. C f CV (TT) HA 0.09 - ~100 6. CV (TT) HA 0.37 - -100 7. GNDT (TT) HA 0.08 - -100 Total Land HA 1.38 1.250 -9 Total Gross Margin RP 197,620 283,089 43 Family Labor Manday 255 232 -9 Hired Labor Manday 29 33 14 Total Labor Manday 284 265 -7 Animal Draft Hired AWD 6.5 9.5 46 Operating Capital RP 29,925 39,025 30 Return/Hectare RP 51,528 132,692 158 Return/Manday 677 1,041 54 Source: Computed. *For explanation of abbreviations see Table C.1, Appendix C. 126 These differences can be attributed probably to the fact that North Lampung is a relatively newly Opened area for transmigrants and use of modern inputs was just recently introduced to the representative farm. So the representative farm has not yet sufficient time to make all necessary adjust- ments to achieve Optimum farm organization. The other factor that may have contributed to these differences between Optimal and actual plan of the representative farm is the data limita- tion. Information obtained was based on the "memory" of the respondent farmers which, in the interview, covered a whole crOp year of 1978/79. Problems may have develOped in measuring, for example, the area of land cultivated and yields. If we assume that the results of the linear program- ming applications are valid, the implication from the analy- sis is that there is some potential for achieving an increase in farm income and improvement in the efficiencies of resource use measured by the average return to resources such as land, labor, and Operating capital. This increase in farm income could be realized through reallocation of resources among crOp production activities as indicated by the optimal plan. The slow process of adjustment in the farm organiza- tion toward the optimal plan may be due to the limited knowledge of the representative farmer. A more intensive extension effort backed by field research could probably Speed up the process. 127 The comparison of Optimal and actual plans under existing resource levels for Central Lampung is presented in Table 4.16. The table shows that there was no significant increase in farm income from the actual, even though there is a significant change in the crOp enterprise combination. Sole crOps of upland rice and cassava were eliminated in the optimal plan, while there was a significant change in the land devoted to crOp mixtures. For the crOp mixture of corn f cassava - soybeans, land devoted to it in the optimal plan covered 0.518 hectares and in the actual plan only 0.13 hectares, an increase of 298 percent. The increase of land devoted to this crOp mixture was at the expense of the crOp mixture of corn + upland rice f cassava and the single crOps of upland rice and cassava. There was an increase of 20 percent of land devoted to crop mixture of corn - soybeans + cassava under the new technology. Family labor use was decreased in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan by 11 percent. Returns to labor increased in the optimal plan by 3 percent compared to the actual plan. Hired labor use increased by 51 percent and use of animal draft power increased by 35 percent. The impact on Operating capital was to increase its use in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan by 29 percent. Return to land was higher in the optimal plan by 25 percent. If the results of the linear programming are valid then there is a small potential to increase farm income, Table 4.16.--A Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the 128 Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in Central Lampung. Actual Optimal Change Item* Unit Plan Plan Percent l. C + ULR f CV (NT) HA 0.340 0.262 -23 2. C + ULR f CV (TT) HA 0.200 0.240 20 3. C - SB f CV (NT) HA 0.130 0.518 298 4. LLR (NT) HA 0.240 0.240 0 5. ULR (TT) HA 0.100 - -100 6. CV (NT) HA 0.250 - ' -100 Total Land HA 1.260 1.260 0 Total Gross Margin RP 178,500 182,238 2 Family Labor Manday 245 219 -11 Hired Labor Manday 47 71 51 Total Labor Manday 292 290 -1 Animal Draft Hired AWD 9.5 12.8 35 Operating Capital RP 54,250 70,000 29 Return/Hectare RP 41,548 52,074 25 Return/Manday Labor RP 568 585 3 Source: Computed. *For explanation of abbreviations Appendix C. see Table C.1, 129 but high potential to increase efficiency of the resource use such as land (as indicated by the average returns to land). This high increase in return to land resource but small increase in farm income could be achieved through the reallocation of resources among crOp enterprises as indicated in the optimal plan. Then the question may arise is whether the small increase of 2 percent in farm income is worthwhile to make the changes with a decrease in family labor input by 11 percent (absolute decrease by 26 mandays) while increases in use of hired labor by 51 percent (absolute increase by 24 mandays), increase in use of hired animal draft by 35 per- cent (absolute increase by 3.3 animal working days) and its consequences of increasing operating capital by 29 percent (absolute increase by Rp15,750). Taken into account risk factor, it is likely that the farmer would not make any changes in order to obtain a nonsignificant increase in his income. The comparison of actual and Optimal plans under existing resources in South Lampung is presented in Table 4.17. The table shows that gross farm income in the optimal plan is higher compared to the actual plan by 6 percent. There were changes in the farm organization. The crOp mix- ture of upland rice + corn - soybeans was eliminated in the optimal plan. Sole crOp of cassava was eliminated in the optimal plan. There was a significant change in the land devoted to each crOp mixture. Land devoted to the cr0p mixture of 130 Table 4.17.--A Comparison of Actual and Optimal Plan of the Representative Farm Under New Technology and Existing Resource Levels in South Lampung. Actual Optimal Change Item* Unit Plan Plan Percent l. ULR - SB/CV (NT) HA 0.360 0.325 -11 2. SB - SB - SB/CV (NT) HA 0.240 0.321 34 3. ULR + C - SB/CV (NT) HA 0.280 0.454 62 4. ULR + C/CV (TT) HA 0.200 - -100 5. CV (TT) HA 0.020 - -100 Total Land HA 1.100 1.100 0 Total Gross Margin RP 181,425 192,970 6 Family Labor Manday 288 257 -ll Hired Labor Manday 27 5 -440 Total Labor Manday 315 262 -17 Operating Capital RP 18,000 7,500 -58 Return/Hectare RP 49,623 63,223 27 Return/Manday Labor RP 664 731 10 Source: Computed. *For explanation of abbreviations Appendix C. see Table C.1, 131 upland rice - soybeans was smaller by 11 percent in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan. Triple crOps of soybeans increased by 34 percent compared to the actual plan, and land devoted to the crOp mixture of upland rice + corn - soybeans increased by 62 percent compared to the actual plan. The crOpping pattern was less diversified in the Optimal plan than in the actual plan. There was a decrease in family labor input in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan by 11 percent. Hired labor use declined to about one-fifth of the level of the actual plan and total labor use decreased by 17 percent in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan. There was also a decrease in Operating capital by 58 percent in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan due to reduced hired labor input in the Optimal plan. Even though there were decreases in resource use in the Optimal plan compared to the actual plan, gross income and returns to resources were higher in the Optimal plan. Returns per hectare were higher by 27 percent and returns to labor were higher by 10 percent. Assuming that the results of the linear programming analysis are valid, then there was only a small potential to increase farm income and a small increase in returns to labor, but a substantial Opportunity to increase the produc- tivity of the land resource. These increases can be obtained through the reallocation of resources among the cr0p enter- prises as indicated in the Optimal plan under the new tech- nology. It should also be noted that the only new input 132 which has been used after the introduction of the new tech- nology on the representative farm in South Lampung is insecticides. 4.6 Summary of the Results from Linear Programming Analysis The results of the analysis from the empirical data collected in the study area has been presented in this Chapter. The findings indicated that some of the cropping patterns have a better competitive position in the Optimal plan under the new technology than under the traditional one, i.e., in North Lampung this would be mixed cropping of upland rice - soybeans, in Central Lampung this would be mixed cropping of corn i cassava - soybeans, and for South Lampung this would be mixed cropping of upland rice + corn - soybeans. The crOpping pattern is less diversified under the new technology. There is a comparative advantage in producing a specific crop with specific crOpping patterns in each subregion as shown by the results of the linear programming analysis as well as by observations. North Lampung has a comparative advantage in pro- ducing cassava and upland rice with crOpping patterns con- sisting of crOpping mixtures: corn + upland rice i cassava. Central Lampung has a comparative advantage in production of rice and cassava with crOp mixtures: corn - soybeans % cas- sava, and corn + upland rice f cassava. South Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing soybeans with crOp 133 mixtures: corn + upland rice - soybean, upland rice - soy- beans, and triple crOps of soybeans in one crOpping year. The introduction of currently available new techno- lOgy to the upland farming in Lampung indicates from the results of the linear programming analysis that there is some potential to increase food production and income of the farmers, and increase resource use and productivity. The highest potential is in North Lampung which is a relatively newly settled transmigration area. This may be due to the fact that the representative farm has not yet enough time to make required adjustments towards the Optimal farm organi- zation. For the representative farms in Central and South Lampung the results of the analysis indicated that there is little potential to increase farm income and food production through the adOption of the currently available new techno- logy. It is also noted that in Pugung Raharja village (South Lampung) insecticides is the only new input used by the representative farm. The results of the analysis of the representative farm in Central Lampung show that the marginal value product of irrigated land is much higher than the marginal value product of dryland. This may imply that the conversion of upland/dryland into irrigated land is one of the strategies to increase both food crOp production and farm income of the small upland farmers. Labor during the peak demand months is a limiting factor in increasing food crOp production and farm income 134 in the study area, eSpecially for weeding under the new technology, and for land preparation under the traditional technology. Hired labor is limited in the peak seasons since there are no landless farmers in the study area. The use of animal draft power and other source of power may release part of this labor constraint. Medium to long term credit may be needed for investment in additional sources of power (e.g., cows, small tractors). The representative farmers need no credit for Oper- ating capital if they practice a mixed crOpping pattern which distributes cash income more evenly through the year. This is accomplished by selling their products after harvest of cassava in September, soybeans in February, corn in March, and rice in May. In this Chapter the analysis emphasized the compari- son of the Optimal farm organization under traditional and under the new technolOgy to present the likely effects of the introduction of the new technology. The comparison of the effects of the new technology with existing resource levels between the three subregions sheds some light on the comparative advantage in producing specific crOps with Specific cropping patterns. The analysis also sheds some light on the importance of some of the limiting resources in the Optimal plan under the new technology. In the follow- ing Chapter the normative supply functions and estimates of price elasticities of the major crOps will be discussed. CHAPTER V NORMATIVE SUPPLY FUNCTIONS FOR MAJOR FOOD CROPS UNDER TRADITIONAL AND NEW TECHNOLOGIES 5.1 Introduction The previous chapter dealt with the analysis of the changes in the optimal plan of allocation of farm resources as a new technology is introduced to the traditional farm- ing. The analysis emphasized the effects of the new tech- nology on farm income, crop enterprise combinations, resource use and their productivities, and identification of some of the constraints. In this chapter the examination will be on the effect of the new technology on the major food crops supply functions and elasticities on the representative farms in the study area. In Indonesia the major food crops are rice, maize or corn, and cassava. For 1977 rice harvested covered 8.8 million hectares and total production 23.9 million tons of unhulled rice, corn harvested included 2.6 million hectares and total production of 2.8 million tons, and cassava har- vested was 1.36 million hectares and a total production of 12.17 million tons (Asian Development Bank, 1978). In terms 135 136 of human consumption, rice is predominant providing about one half of all calories. Corn provides about a quarter and cassava about one-fifth of all calories. For example, if the relative price of rice declined relative to the other staple food crops, rice will be con- sumed in a larger quantity, and vice versa. Income elas- ticity of rice in Indonesia is 0.6 which is very high (Timmer, 1974; Parhusip, 1976). Rice production has bene- fitted from the government investment program such as irri- gation, credit and extension programs (BIMAS), and research programs in Indonesia. Rice production is still lagging behind the increasing demand due to the rapid population and income growth. The average annual import of rice is about two million tons since the late 19703 and now Indo- nesia has become the largest rice importer in the world. In Lampung, rice, corn, and cassava are also the major food crOps. Area harvested and total production of these crops for Lampung province is presented in Table B1 through Table B3 of Appendix B. Corn production has deteri- orated since 1973 and cassava production only has recently had a significant increase. Lampung is still a rice deficit area and local rice production cannot compete with the increasing demand for rice. Corn is produced mostly for domestic consumption. Some corn is exported and locally traded. For example, in 1977, 3,888 tons were exported and 15,801 tons were traded to the other provinces, especially to Java. Cassava is also produced mostly for domestic 137 consumption in the rural area as well as in the urban areas. Exports and other uses of cassava are fairly small, probably less than 15 percent of total production (Dixon, 1979; Jones, 1978). The low prices received by the farmers for these crops have often been cited as one of the causes of the slow growth or even deterioration in their output. Many studies have shown that small farmers are rational and respond positively to increases in commodity prices (Gotsch and Falcon, 1974). Given this small farmer's behavior, then policy makers have sometimes been called upon to raise producer prices in order to increase food production. An accurate knowledge of the price elastic- ities of supply of these major crops is required to make a correct decision in a right direction and appropriate pro- ducer price increases in order to increase output by the required amount. The adoption of the new technology shifts the pro- duction function and many times changes the farmer's response to commodity price changes (Gotsch and Falcon, 1974). Where rapid technological change is being experi- enced by the farmers, the previous estimates (if any) of price elasticities will not be a very good guide to the future supply response of the farmers in producing these crops. A recent estimate of price elasticities of these major crops may be needed in order to provide a basis for meaningful public decisions. 138 According to Heady (1961) there are two major direc- tions from which empirical estimates of agricultural supply have been attacked in the past. The positive or descrip- tive approach is the prediction of the quantitative rela- tionship among variables as they actually do exist at a point of time, or have existed over a period of time. The other is the normative or predictive approach which refers to what ought to exist, under certain assumptions. The major tools for positive analysis are regression procedures, e.g., econometric analysis, which attempts predictions from observations drawn out of the "actual operating world." The major tools for normative analysis include budgeting and programming. Here, certain assumptions are usually made about goal(s) and actions of decision makers. Both positive and normative approaches have been used and are being used because of the limitations of the estimates derived by each. The most traditional positive approach is econo- metric analysis of aggregate time series data. This approach is descriptive since the estimation of the parameters is based on the past behavior of producers in response to pro- duct price changes and other relevant economic variables. This positive analysis of supply functions indicates responses to the real world in the past but is restricted in its ability to estimate what might be in the future when there are changes in structures or new variables. A normative approach to estimation of supply func- tions is by programming individual farms for optimal 139 solutions, indicating farmer's potential response under the assumptions of farm income maximization, perfect knowledge about prices, technological changes and institutional envi- ronmental factors. To the extent that these assumptions fail, a farmer's actual decisions may sometimes differ markedly from those indicated as optimum. Both approaches have their advantages and limita- tions, and they are supplements rather than substitutes for each other. However, when rapid technological change is experienced by the farmers, and when there is a lack of accurate time series data on production and prices at the farm level, then there are definite advantages in the appli- cation of the programming approach. These advantages have been summarized by Buckwell and Hazel (1972). Programming provides a wealth of information on the farm level which is very useful for evaluation of the likely impact of policy on many small farm problems, embodied in a causal system of how individual farms function. It becomes easier to evalu- ate the future impact of policies. The fact that most farmers produce many products and use many resources with various enterprise combinations renders this approach well suited to evaluate the total impact of changes in relative prices on the supply of the individual crops. These advantages may be weighted against the enor— mous data requirements of programming. The supply function estimated by the programming is normative in the sense that it indicates what farmer should produce in order to maximize 140 income. The power of the analysis is dependent on the degree of correspondence between the assumptions made and reality including the structure of constraints, activities included in the model, technological coefficients, prices of outputs and inputs, and how risk factors are taken into account in the model (Heady, 1961). The normative approach by its nature may lead to an upward biased estimate of the supply function and elasticities (Anderson et‘al., 1965; Sheehy e5 21., 1964). There is no clear way to estimate to what extent normative quantities should be adjusted to closely approximate the actual supply response. Krenz et 31. (1962) have suggested that the supply function could be made "less normative" or more realistic by including in the linear programming only production activities that the farmer is likely to consider. The normative supply function estimated for the representative farm is derived from the linear programming model presented earlier. Parametric (or variable price) programming is used to derive the optimal output of the commodity concerned as its price is varied within an appropriate range while other prices are held constant. Variable price programming derives a supply function that can be formalized as follows (Krenz et 31., 1962): QA = f (P1, P2, PA, . . . Pn, R1, R2, . . . Rn, C1, C2, . . . Cn) in which: 141 QA = quantity of A produced (PA varied) P1 to Pn = prices of factors and products at the farm level 1R1 to Rn = the fixed resources of the farm (firm) C1 to Cn = coefficients of production on the farm in all production alternatives considered. The supply function also considered alternative products that may be produced with the given resources, at specified prices for factors, and technology of the farm under con- sideration. The supply function obtained is normative in the sense that it indicates what a farmer would plan to produce if he intended to maximize profits. The functional relationship of price and quantity of the commodity derived from linear programming is dis- continuous and in the form of a "step" function. Burt (1964) defined a step function as "a function such that a range is divided into a finite number of intervals with the dependent variable constant on a given interval." Graphically a step function appears as a series of steps as shown in Figure 5.1. By putting a consumption constraint or household requirement in the model, then that amount should be produced irrespective of its price (subsistence production). According to Kottke (1967) the stepped supply function consists of two parts. The horizontal segment depicted in Figure 5.1 is identified as marginal cost. The vertical segment of the step is identified by applying 142 P' (MC) SP + SM S? J:“’ Mcc ._ f ----- MCb an ~ ‘— ~ .4 SP = Subsistence Production Mca ‘” ------ SM = Marketed Surplus I ‘r 4* ‘ Os 03 Qb QC Q (Quantity of Output) Figure 5.1. Farm-Firm Step Supply Function. 143 the profit maximizing criterion of MR 3 MC. The vertical segments or optimal solutions and price ranges for the steps can be formulated as follows: f(P) = Qs for 0 i P i MCa = Qa for MCa < P i MCb = Qb for MCb < P : MCc Qc for MCc < P where MC is the marginal cost of producing Q, and P is the price of Q. The range of the vertical segments of the supply function is based on the profit maximizing criterion P = MR = MC. The optimum crop enterprise combination, and the optimum output, holds for all the prices included in the range of the vertical portion of any one step. The "stepped" characteristic of the supply function results from the finite number of production alternatives and rigid resource restrictions in the programming model. The number of steps and corners are the function of the number of production alternatives and restrictions. Including more production alternatives and restrictions will generate a normative supply function with more and smaller steps. A supply function derived by means of parametric programming is static and in partial equilibrium in that no changes are assumed other than the price of the product (e.g., no changes in asset structure, no changes in tech- nological coefficients). Supply elasticities associated 144 with normative supply functions are biased upwards when compared with those obtained from time series data in which implicit are time lags, risk and uncertainty, and other behavioral factOrs that influence farmer's decisions to produce the output (Heady et 31., 1961). 5.2 Normative Supply Function of Rice, Corn, and Cassava In this section the supply functions for rice, corn, and cassava derived from the linear programming models described in Chapter III will be presented. Normative sup- ply functions for the three crops were derived under tra- ditional and new technologies with existing resource levels. The effects of releasing family labor constraints under the new technology were also examined. In the interpretation of the results caution must be taken since they were derived from one representative farm based on a purposive sample that was drawn from a limited number of samples and limited geographical areas. As a complete case only the analysis of the representative farm of North Lampung will be presented. 5.2.1 Rice Supply Function In order to obtain the normative supply function for rice, the price of rice in the selling activities were varied over the range of Rp 100 per kilogram to Rp 300 per kilogram and then corresponding optimal solutions were 145 obtained.1 The quantity of rice produced at each price level was obtained from optimal solutions. The comparison of the results under traditional and new technologies within exiSting resource levels and new technology with labor increased is presented in Table 5.1. The comparison shows the likely impact of the new technology on the supply of rice on the representative farm in North Lampung. The introduction of the new technology resulted in a shift in the supply curve outward to the right, indicat- ing that the new technology has the effect of increasing the quantity of rice produced at each price. The increase of rice output comes from the expansion of acreage under cultivation of rice and an increase in rice yields. The table also shows that the normative supply functions for rice under the new technology and increased availability of family labor increased the quantity of rice produced at each price level. The effectiveness of the new technology was enhanced by increasing the availability of family labor during the peak seasons. The effects of the new technology and the increase in availability of family labor are also shown in Figure 5.2. The effect of relaxing credit constraints was not analyzed here, on the consideration that operating capital 1The prevailing rice price in the study area is Rp 100 per kilogram. The price range used in the supply anal— ysis may not represent the expected range of price increase, due to the government control on rice price. 146 Table 5.1.--A Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Rice Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources of the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Traditional. New Technology Technology with Existing Existing Resource Labor Increased Resources Price Price Price Range Quantity Range Quantity Range Quantity (RP) (Kg) (RP) (Kg) (RP) (K9) 0-85 500 0-97 500 0-85 500 86-121 1144 100-121 1569 86-115 1602 122-257 1144 122-320 1569 116-363 1602 258-900 1153 321-666 1539 364—1326 1689 Source: Computed. 147 pares (RP)6000 'I'T/ER NT/ER NT/gZIV 5009 400» 3001 200" 100v ‘_ _____ _.._ _.._ _ - .. - .. .. _... _ _ - oLA’Ngbo 600 760 800 900 1000 1100 1100 1300 $400 1500 1600 1700 QUANTITY (KG) Figure 5.2. Normative Supply Functions for Rice Under Traditional and New Technologies of the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER = Traditional Technology with Existing Resources NT/ER = New Technology with Existing Resources NT/LV = New Technology with Increased Family Labor 148 Table 5.2.--A Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Rice Price Varied on the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Price Quantity Sold (Kg) Farm Income (Rp) (RP) TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV 100 644 1069 1102 172302 283089 303314 115 644 1069 1102 181966 299118 319848 150 644 1069 1102 204514 336518 358418 400 653 1039 1089 366873 577925 611120 Source: Computed. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER = Traditional Technology with Existing Resource NT/ER = New Technology with Existing Resource Levels NT/LV = New Technology with Increased Family Labor Income = Gross Margin 149 is not a constraint due to a more even distribution of cash income to the farmers as they practiced multiple cropping. Table 5.2 shows a comparison of farm income under traditional and new technologies under existing resources and with labor increased. Both rice production and farm income are increased under the new technology at all price levels. These increases are generated by the increase in the availability of family labor under the new technology. The implication is that the introduction of the new tech- nology has a potential for increasing rice production and farm income. These increases are enhanced by the increase in the availability of family labor. 5.2.2 Corn or Maize Supply Functions The normative supply functions for corn were also derived by variable price programming (parametrically vary- ing the price of corn) over the range 60 Rupiah per kilo- gram to 561 Rupiah per kilogram, then obtaining the corres- ponding optimal solutions.1 Table 5.3 shows a comparison of the quantity of corn produced at each price level under traditional and new technologies with existing resource levels and increased family labor under the new technology. 1The prevailing price of corn in the study area is Rp 60 per kilogram, so this price range may be unrealistic. The price range should be wide in any case in order to see the effect of price changes on corn production. 150 Table 5.3.--A Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Corn Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resources and Labor Increased for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. New Technology Traditional Technology Existing Resource Labor Increased Existing Resource Price Price Price Range Quantity Range Quantity Range Quantity (RP) (KG) (RP) (KG) (RP) (KG) 0-37 150 0-46 150 0-47 150 37-80 238 47-79 501 48-94 491 81—212 268 99-135 499 94-200 484 212-300 268 145-300 502 201-300 484 301-561 276 301-717 502 301-421 484 Source: Computed. 151 With results similar to the case of rice, the adoption of the new technology increased the quantity of corn produced at all price levels (shifted the supply curve outward to the right). The increase in corn production is the result of an increase in yields and the increase in the acreage under corn cultivation in a mixture. These supply func- tions are presented in Figure 5.3. An increase in family labor does increase in corn production and farm income. The results of the analysis show that there is some potential for increasing corn production and farm income through the adoption of the new technology. The increase in family labor availability will enhance corn production and farm income. Under the new technology corn is produced in a mixed cropping system. Table 5.4 shows a comparison of farm income under traditional and new technologies with existing resources and labor increased. Both production and farm income are increased under the new technology as in the case of rice. This is also true for corn. The increase in the avail- ability of family labor enhances corn production and farm income. The implication is that the introduction of the new technology has a potential to increase both corn pro- duction and farm income. These increases are also enhanced by the increase in the availability of family labor. PRICE (RP) 550 500 450 400» 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 152 Figure 5.3. r I NT/ER TT/ER ' NT/LV r— F 150 250 350 450 550 650 QUANTITY (KG) Normative Supply Functions for Corn Under Traditional and New Technologies of the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV Traditional Technology with Existing Resources New.Technology with Existing Resources New Technology with Increased Family Labor 153 Table 5.4.--A Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Corn Price Varied for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Price Quantity Sold (KG) Farm Income (RP) (RP) TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV 60 88 351 336 172302 283089 303658 100 113 349 334 176811 297032 316685 200 113 352 334 188081 332152 350113 300 113 352 334 199352 367352 383541 350 121 352 334 205402 384952 400255 Source: Computed. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER = Traditional Technology with Existing Resources NT/ER = New Technology with Existing Resource Levels NT/LV = New Technology with Increased Family Labor Farm Income = Gross Margin 154 5.2.3 Cassava Supply Functions The normative supply functions for cassava were obtained by parametrically varying the price of cassava over the range of 17 Rupiah per kilogram to 60 per kilogram,1 and then obtaining the corresponding optimal solutions. Table 5.5 shows a comparison of the quantity of cassava produced at each price level under traditional and new tech- nologies and at an increased level of labor under the new technology. At all price levels the production of cassava is higher under the new technology than under the tradi- tional technology. An increase of family labor availability has a positive impact on cassava production. The supply curve of cassava under the new technology shift upward to the right as shown in Figure 5.4. The likely impact of the adoption of the new technology will increase cassava production and farm income. Table 5.6 shows a comparison of farm income under the traditional and new technologies. Farm income is higher under the new technology than under the traditional technology at all price levels. Increased family labor availability enhanced both cassava production and farm income. 1The prevailing price of cassava in the study area is Rp 17 per kilogram, the price range is realistic since demand for cassava is strong due to a recent dramatic increase in the capacity of cassava processing industries in Lampung. Also the prospects for cassava prices are favorable in domestic markets and abroad. 155 Table 5.5.--A Comparison of Normative Supply Functions for Cassava Under Traditional and New Technologies with Existing Resource and Labor Increased for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Traditional Technology New Technology Existing Resource Existing Resource Labor Increased Price Range Quantity Price Range Quantity Price Range Quantity (RP) (KG) (RP) (KG) (RP) (KG) 0-11.0 3000 0-16 3000 0-7 3000 11-18.5 4314 16.2-18.3 9718 7-9 10384 19-21 5169 19.7-21.5 9720 19.5-20 11482 24-28 5380 24.3-31.6 9778 20-48 11482 28-34 6151 34-48.6 10729 48-168 13111 36-47 8415 48.6-79.6 13011 168-283 13111 47-90 8523 Source: Computed. ‘l 156 PRICE (RP) 110 ' NT/LV . 1001, F 90)» Tr/[ER- _— 801» 700 NT/ER 60h 50m ...... 40" r - ‘- - - - - - NT/LV 301- I - f 20” _----' NT/ER ----- 1. (I J 0v . . . . . j , , , I r O 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 80009000 10000 12000 14000 11000 13000 QUANTITY (KG) Figure 5.4. Normative Supply Functions for Cassava under Traditional and New Technologies of the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER = Traditional Technology with Existing Resources NT/ER = New Technology with Existing Resources NT/LV = New Technology with Increased Family Labor 157 Table 5.6.--A Comparison of Farm Income Under Traditional and New Technologies with Cassava Price Varied for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Price Quantity Sold (KG) Farm Income (RP) (RP) TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV 17 1314 6718 7384 172302 283089 303658 20 2169 6720 8482 176663 303237 325903 25 2380 6778 8482 188023 337076 368368 30 3151 6778 8482 201369 370925 410784 40 5415 7729 8482 249015 445598 495618 50 5523 7729 10111 303457 526166 583711 60 5523 7729 10111 358687 603458 684822 Source: Computed. Explanation of Abbreviations: TT/ER NT/ER NT/LV Farm Income = Gross Margin Traditional Technology with Existing Resources New Technology with Existing Resources New Technology with Increased Family Labor 158 The effects of commodity relative price increases under the new technology show that increases in relative price of cassava has the largest impact on farm income. For example a 50 percent increase in the relative price of cassava (from Rp 17 to Rp 25.50 per kilogram), ceteris paribus, farm income increases by 20 percent from Rp 283,089 to Rp 340,465. An increase in the relative price of corn by 50 percent (from Rp 60 to Rp 90 per kilogram), ceteris paribus, farm income increases by 4 percent from Rp 283,089 to Rp 293,542. An increase in relative price of rice by 50 percent (from Rp 100 to Rp 150), ceteris paribus, farm income increases by 19 percent from Rp 283,089 to Rp 336,518. 5.3 The Effects of the New Technology on the Price Elasticities of the Supply of the Major Food Crops The ultimate purpose of the supply function analy- sis generally is the estimation of price elasticity. To complete the analysis of the supply functions of the major food crops, i.e., rice, corn, and cassava, the estimation of the price elasticities of these supply functions will proceed. For the "stepped" supply function, estimation of the price elasticity is not as clear-cut as the estimation of the price elasticity of smooth supply functions. Esti- mation of the stepped supply function is meaningless unless the function is transformed into a smooth or continuous supply curve. 159 Some methods are available to transform a "stepped" supply function into a smooth supply function. Krenz (1960) used optimum quantities and their corresponding prices as the observations to be used as data for a least square regression analysis to estimate price elasticity as in a continuous function. According to Burt (1964) the mid- points of the vertical portions of the steps are more stable with respect to price changes and therefore are used as values for price (independent variable). This method will be used in this section to estimate price elasticities of supply of the major food crops under traditional and new technologies. A continuous supply function is fitted to the data presented as stepped supply functions in section 5.2. The model is based on only a single independent variable since it is assumed there are no changes in factors affecting supply except its price. The general functional form is as follows: Q=f(P) where: Q = quantity of commodity produced in kilograms per crop year P = price of commodity in Rupiah per kilogram Each vertical part of the step function is treated as an observation on the dependent variable. It has been men- tioned before that price production is stable at the 160 midpoints of the vertical parts of the steps (and therefore these midpoints will be used as values for the independent variable). But it should be born in mind that the data generated by this procedure may not meet the normality and independence assumptions, so that statistical inferences and probability statements cannot be made. Functional relationships to be considered are as in the following forms: Q = 80 + 31 P (linear relationship) Q = BO + 81 P + 82 P2 (quadratic relationship) Q = Bo + 81 log P (semi-log relationship) 1n Q = 80 + 81 log P (double-log relationship) The criteria to be used for choosing the "best" fit of the functional relationship are: size of adjusted R square, the sign of the price coefficient (81) and F- value for the regression mean square. For estimating these functional relationships by using the SPSS (Statistical Package for Social Sciences) by Nie, 1975. The estimated supply equations for these major food crops are presented in Table 5.7, Table 5.8, and Table 5.9 for rice, corn, and cassava respectively. For the rice supply equations the R2 are low and all coeffici- ents are not significant at 5 percent level. Corn supply equation R25 are also low and all coefficients are not significant at the 5 percent level, except the corn supply equation under traditional technology. This equation has 161 Table 5.7.--Estimated Supply Functions for Rice Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Technology and Functional B 8 -2 Resource Level Form 0 1 a,Y Traditional Tech- Semi-log -86.9 501.5 0.30 2.3 nology and Exist- ing Resources New Technology Double log 2.1 0.44 0.45 3.5 and Existing Resources New Technology Double-log 2.4 0.31 0.25 2.0 and Labor Increased* All of the coefficients are not significant at 5 percent level Source: Computed. *It was assumed that the family members are willing to work each month as long as in the months of the peak season. 162 Table 5.8.--Estimated Supply Functions for Corn Under Traditional and New Technologies for the ReSpresentative Farm in North Lampung. Technology and Functional B B §2 F Resource Level Form 0 l a,y Traditional Tech- Semi-log 60.9 87.0* 0.80 16.8 nology and Exist- ing Resources New Technology Smi-lOg -47.0 232.1 0.43 4.0 and Existing Resources New Technology Double-log 1.76 0.40 0.56 6.1 and Labor Increaseda Source: Computed. *Significant at 5 percent. aIt was assumed that the family members are willing to work as long as in the months of peak season. 163 Table 5.9.--Estimated Supply Functions for Cassava Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. A Technology and Functional B B §2 F Resource Level Form 0 l a,y Traditional Tech- Double-log 3.04 0.5** 8.95 111.2 nology and Exist- ing Resources New Technology Semi-log -2909.9 8712** 0.82 28.8 and Existing Resources New Technology Semi-log 3055.9 4721.7** 0.57 and Increased Labora Source: Computed. *Significant at 5 percent. **Significant at 1 percent. aIt was assumed that the family members are willing to work as long as in the months of peak season. 164 R2 = 0.80 and the 81 coefficient is significant at the 5 percent level. The R2 for the cassava supply equations are high at 0.95, 0.82, and 0.57 under traditional technol- ogy-with existing resources, new technology with existing resources, and under the new technology with increased family labor respectively. All coefficients for cassava supply equations are significant at 1 percent and at 5 per- cent levels. Elasticities of supply of the major food crops with respect to their own prices were calculated by using the following formula: Price elasticities for rice supply were calculated at vari- ous price levels ranging from 42.5 Rupiah to 579 Rupiah per kilogram. These calculated price elasticities for rice are shown in Table 5.10. All elasticities are positive and indicate the percentage increase in quantity of rice produced in response to a 1 percent increase in rice price. Under traditional technology, the price elasticity for rice supply varies from 1.0 at the price of 42.5 Rupiah per kilogram to 0.44 at the price of 579 Rupiah per kilogram. Price elasticities of rice are lower than one (except for rice price lower than the existing price of 100 Rupiah per kilogram). Rice supply functions can be considered inelas- tic. 165 Table 5.10.--Estimated Price Elasticities of Rice Supply Functions Under‘Traditional and New Techno- logies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung.w Elasticities Price . (Rp/KG) Tradtional Tech- New Technology New Technology nology and Ex15t- and EXIsting and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 42.5 1.00 0.44 0.31 103.5 0.44 0.44 0.31 139.5 0.44 0.44 0.31 579 0.44 0.44 0.31 Source: Computed. 166 The price elasticities of rice supply under tradi- tional and new technologies with existing resources are con- stant at 0.44. Price elasticities of rice supply are also conStant at 0.31 under the new technology with increased family labor. The supply of rice under the new technology is inelastic with constant elasticity irrespective of price levels (the best fit is the supply equation in double logarithmic form). As family labor increased under the new technology, the supply of rice became more inelastic. This means that response of rice supply to a 1 percent change in the price of rice is lower under the new technology than under the traditional technology, but it is not necessarily true in terms of absolute changes of rice output, as can be seen later in this section. In all cases the price elasticities of rice supply functions are constant within the price range from 100 Rupiah per kilogram (existing rice price in the study area) to 579 Rupiah per kilogram. Table 5.11 shows the price elasticities of corn supply functions. All coefficients are less than one except at a corn price at 18.5 Rupiah per kilogram under the new technology and existing resources. With current price of corn at 60 Rupiah per kilogram in the study area, it is likely that the supply of corn is inelastic. The supply of corn is more inelastic under traditional tech- nology. 80 under the new technology, corn supply is more responsive to its price changes than under the traditional 167 Table 5.ll.--Estimated Price Elasticities of Corn Supply Functions Under Traditional and New Techno- logies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Elasticities Price . . (RP/KG) Traditional Tech- New Technology New Technology nology and EXIst- and EXisting and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 18.5 0.58 1.54 0.40 63.0 0.37 0.46 0.40 146.5 0.32 0.46 0.40 256 0.32 0.46 0.40 476 0.32 0.46 0.40 Source: Computed. 168 technology. The effect of the adoption of the new tech- nology on the price elasticity of corn supply is different from rice. Increases in the price of corn under the new technology is mOre effective in increasing production than is the case with rice. Table 5.12 shows the price elasticities for cassava supply functions at the price range from 7.2 Rupiah per kilogram to 91 Rupiah per kilogram. All elasticities are less than one, except at the price level of 7.2 Rupiah per kilogram (which is much lower than the 17 Rupiah per kilo- gram existing price) under the new technology. 80 the supply of cassava is also inelastic but less inelastic than corn and rice supply curves. Supply of cassava is less inelastic under the new technology compared to the tradi- tional technology. This implies that the increase in price of cassava is more effective in increasing its production under the new technology than under the traditional tech- nology. In the case of the new technology, the price elas- ticities of cassava decreased as its price increased. This means that price increases for cassava is less effective to increase production at higher price levels. In case the policy or program objective is to increase food production, the absolute increase in pro- duction in response to increases in crop prices is more relevant than the price elasticity itself as indication of the effectiveness of the price incentive. These absolute changes or increases in the major food crop production in 169 Table 5.12.--Estimated Price Elasticities of Cassava Supply Functions Under Traditional and New Techno- logies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Elasticities Price d' ' 1 h N h 1 N T h 1 (Rp/KG) Tra itiona Tec - ew Tec no ogy ew ec no ogy nology and EXISt- and EXISting and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 7.20 0.50 2.90 1.57 14.75 0.50 0.89 0.45 20.75 0.50 0.89 0.41 26.00 0.50 0.89 0.41 41.50 0.50 0.81 0.36 91.00 0.50 0.66 0.36 Source: Computed. 170 response to a 1 percent increase in its price are shown in Table 5.13, Table 5.14, and Table 5.15 for rice, corn, and cassava respectively. Table 5:13 shows that the absolute increase of rice output in response to a 1 percent increase in its price is highest under the new technology. This implies that price increase is more effective to induce rice production in an absolute sense under the new technology with existing resources than under the traditional technology. Table 5.14 shows that the absolute increase in corn output in response to a 1 percent increase in its price is much higher than under traditional technology. This implies that price increase is much more effective to induce an increase in production of corn under the new technology than under the traditional technology. Table 5.15 shows that the absolute increase in cassava output in response to a 1 percent increase in its price under the new technology with existing resource was more than triple the level under the traditional technology. Absolute increases in cassava output under the new tech- nology and increase in labor availability is more than double the level of the traditional technology. These calculations imply that price increases are much more effective in expanding cassava production under the new technology than under the traditional systems. So even though the price elasticity of cassava supply under the new technology with increase in labor is lower than under the 171 Table 5.13.--Absolute Increases in Production of Rice in ReSponse to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Increase in Output (KG) Traditional Tech- New Technology New Technology IRpiiG) nology and Exist- and Existing and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 42.5 5.00 2.20 1.55 103.5 5.03 6.90 4.97 139.5 5.03 6.90 4.97 579.0 5.07 6.77 4.93 Source: Computed. 172 Table 5.14.--Absolute Increases in Corn Production in Response to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Increase in Output (KG) IRliiG) Traditional Tech- New Technology New Technology p nology and Exist- and Existing and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 18.5 0.87 2.31 0.60 63.0 0.88 2.30 1.96 146.5 0.86 2.30 1.94 256.0 0.86 2.30 1.94 476.0 0.86 2.30 1.94 Source: Computed. 173 Table 5.15.--Absolute Increases in Cassava Production in ReSponse to a 1 Percent Increase in Its Price Under Traditional and New Technologies for the Representative Farm in North Lampung. Increase in Output (KG) Price Traditional Tech- New Technology New Technology (RP/KG) nology and Exist- and Existing and Increased ing Resources Resources Labor 7.20 15.0 87.0 47.1 14.75 21.6 86.5 46.7 20.75 25.8 86.5 47.1 26.00 26.9 87.5 47.1 41.50 30.7 86.9 47.2 91.00 42.1 85.8 47.2 Source: Computed. 174 traditional technology, the absolute increase in cassava production in response to a 1 percent increase in its price is higher. In the next chapter the major findings from the empirical analysis on the effects of the new technology on the key farm variables will be summarized and policy impli- cations of these findings will be discussed. The limita- tions of the study and suggestions for further study will be presented. CHAPTER VI SUMMARY, POLICY IMPLICATIONS, LIMITATIONS OF THE STUDY AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH 6.1 Summary The present performance of Indonesian agricultural food crop subsector can be considered unsatisfactory. Food crop production is inadequate, resource productivity and farmers incomes are low. Food production has not kept pace with the growing population, so that Indonesia has to rely on food imports, especially rice. The problem of increas- ing food production is also aggravated by the concentration of population on the island of Java. These conditions hampered the capacity of the agricultural food crOp sub- sector to contribute significantly to general economic development and especially to the industrial sector which relies on agriculture as a source of its raw materials. The problems of unequal distribution of population and low farm income has been partly tackled by the trans- migration program from Java to the outer islands, especi- ally Lampung in South Sumatra. These programs are expected to have the dual strategies of easing Java's population 175 176 pressure and also developing the outer islands. The intended impact is to increase food production, farm income, and growth centers outside Java which will then hopefully attract new migrants. Traditional agriculture and traditional techniques have been identified as the primary causes of the poor per- formance of the agricultural food crop subsector. In order to increase food production, especially rice, the govern- ment has launched a series of programs aimed at increasing food production. The "BIMAS PROGRAM" (mass guidance for increasing rice production) has been underway since 1964/65 with special emphasis on irrigated rice production in Java. A major strategy for technological improvement has been the introduction of modern inputs such as chemical fertilizers, improved seed varieties, insecticides/pesticides and improved cultural practices. These programs to some extent have been successful and have been extended to other food crops such as corn, soybeans, and cassava in the upland farming in the outer islands. Lampung province received considerable attention from the Central Government for its strategic location as a major recipient of the transmigrants from Java and for its great potential for food crop production. Programs for increasing upland food crop production such as upland rice, corn, and cassava have been carried out more intensively in Lampung compared to the other outer islands. Besides the BIMAS program there is a Japanese technical assistance 177 program called "TANI MAKMUR PROJECT" in Lampung which is introducing new technology into the traditional cropping system. This project also enhances the farmer's organiza- tional abilities to cope with the introduction of the new technology, especially farmer's training, distribution of agricultural inputs, and introduction of revolving funds. The Central Research Institute for Agriculture (CRIA) received technical assistance from the International Rice Research Institute (IRRI) and has conducted multiple crop- ping experiments in Lampung to provide information on the new highly potential cropping systems for the local area in order to increase food production and farm income. Agricultural development theory focuses on the avail- ability and introduction of new high return agricultural inputs. The use of these new inputs could significantly alter the resource use, crop enterprise combinations, as well as farm income. These new technological and economic conditions could have a significant impact on the key farm variables such as cropping patterns, crop enterprise combi- nations, farm income, employment, resource use and resource productivity. This study was conducted in Lampung province where the transmigrants are concentrated and upland farming systems for upland food crop production are the main agricultural activities, and new technology for food crop production has been introduced. The study emphasis is on the small subsistence family farms based on the presumption 178 that the development of small scale farms in Indonesia will be the necessary strategy for increasing food production and incomes of millions of small farmers. The large scale, highly mechanized commercial farms are important to increase agricultural production, but they are excluded in this study for the reasons discussed in the introduction. This study was the first in Lampung with linear pro- gramming approach in which data was obtained from periodic visit survey on small farm operators. The ultimate objec- tives of the government program are to raise farm incomes, output and resource productivity. Quantitative information on the effects of technological changes on farm income, cropping patterns and crop enterprise combinations, resource use and productivity is needed. This information is useful as a basis for the evaluation of current agricultural policies and strategies. The purpose of this study was to explore the extent to which new inputs have been incorporated on the small upland food crops farm and the changes in farm income, crOp enterprise combinations, resource use and productivity, and to estimate price elasticities of the normative supply func- tions of the major food crops. The linear programming approach was used as the framework for analyzing the economics of resource use under the traditional and new technologies. The linear pro- gramming structure is presented in Chapter III. The model was designed to maximize gross margins subject to meeting 179 the minimum requirements for family food crop consumption. The activities in the model included crop production and selling activities, labor hiring activities, fertilizer and insecticide buying activities, food crop consumption and buying activities, capital borrowing activities, and trans- fer activities. Transfer activities are included in order to transfer surplus capital from one month to the next. This model was used to generate optimal plans both under the traditional and new technologies. A comparison of these two optimal plans was used to obtain the likely effects of the adoption of the new technology on the traditional farm- ing system. The data used for this empirical analysis was obtained from both secondary and primary sources but mostly from primary sources. The primary data were collected by interviewing a number of sample representative farmers. The sample farmers were selected by the stratified simple random sampling method. Four villages were selected and from each village twenty-three sample farms were selected at random, so we had ninety-two sample farms at the beginning of the interview. Due to several farms which dropped out for various reasons, there were only eighty- five sample farms used in the final analysis. These sample farms were interviewed every month from August through December 1979. The unit of analysis was a representative farm based on average data from the sample farms from each 180 village. The representative farm sizes were 1.48 hectares, 1.44 hectares, 1.45 hectares, and 1.38 hectares for Adiluih, Bulusari, Pugung Raharja, and Tatakarya villages respec- tively. About 1.27 hectares, 1.25 hectares, 1.10 hectares, and 1.38 hectares of these areas were devoted to food crop production respectively. The family size on the representative farms was 5.3 persons, 5.9 persons, 5.6 persons, and 6.0 persons for Adiluih, Bulusari, Pugung Raharja, and Tatakarya villages respectively. The educational level of the household head of the representative farms was 3.4 years, 3.6 years, 3.0 years, and 3.2 years for these villages. The average family labor available including the farm operator were 2.8, 2.8, 2.9, and 2.t adult male equivalents for Adiluih, Bulusari, Pugung Raharja, and Tatakarya villages respectively. The results of the analysis from the empirical data collected in the study area indicated that there is little potential to increase farm income and food production through the adoption of the currently available new tech- nology on the representative farms in Central and South Lampung. Most of the currently available new technology has been adopted. Some .potential was shown to be present for further adoption of currently available new technology for the representative farm in Tatakarya Village (North Lampung) a relatively newly settled transmigration area compared to the other two subregions of Central and South Lampung. This is maybe due to the lack of time for the 181 representative farm to make the required adjustments toward the optimal farm organization. The findings also indicated some of the cropping patterns have a better competitive position in the optimal plan after the introduction of the new technology than under the traditional technology. These are the mixed cropping of upland rice - soybeans in North Lampung, mixed cropping of corn + cassava - soybeans for Central Lampung, and mixed cropping of upland rice + corn - soybeans in South Lampung. There is a comparative advantage in producing a specific crop with specific cropping patterns in each sub- region as shown by the results of the linear programming analysis under the new technology and by observations. North Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing cassava and upland rice with cropping patterns consisting of crop mixtures: corn + upland rice f cassava and upland rice - soybeans. Central Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing rice and cassava with crop mixtures: corn 7 cassava - soybeans and upland rice + corn 7 cassava. South Lampung has a comparative advantage in producing soybeans with crop mixtures: corn + upland rice - soybeans, upland rice - soybeans, and a triple crop of soybeans in sequence. Turning to resource constraints, labor during peak demand months as expected is a major limiting factor in increasing crOp production and farm income in the study area, especially for land preparation and weeding. The increase of family labor input by working more days and/or 182 more hours in a day would increase farm income significantly. There is also a limited supply of hired labor during the peak seasons which may be due to the absence of landless farmers in the Study area. The use of animal draft power may release part of this labor bottleneck for land prepara- tion. Long term credit may be required by the representa- tive farms for investment in livestock such as cows or buffaloes for animal draft as additional source of power. The introduction of simple mechanical equipment for weed- ing operations need also to be considered to overcome labor bottlenecks for weeding. The analysis of representative farms shown no credit need for operating capital if they practice mixed cropping patterns which distribute their cash income more evenly by selling their products after harvest (cassava in September, soybeans in February, corn in March, and rice in May). The analysis shows that in production of rice, corn, and cassava a mixture of these crops is more profitable than sole crops under the new technology. For estimation of the normative supply schedules of the three major food crops under traditional and new tech- nologies variable price programming was used. The results of this price variable programming are the step supply functions. The results of the analysis for the representa- tive farm in North Lampung show that the adoption of the currently available new technology resulted in a shift in 183 the supply curves outward to the right, indicating that the new technology has the effect of increasing output of rice, corn, and cassava at each price level (shift in supply curves). For example with existing prices for these crops, adoption of new technology caused the supply of rice to increase by 37 percent, corn by 68 percent, and cassava by 123 percent, on the representative farm in North Lampung. The effectiveness of the new technology to increase production would be enhanced by the increase in the avail- ability of labor during the peak seasons. In examining the supply response to a relative price change for each crop the step supply functions were transformed into smooth or continuous supply functions by means of regression analysis. From these continuous supply functions own price elasticities of the three major food crops were estimated. The results of the supply functions estimates show that double-logarithmic and semi-logarithmic forms of relationship were the best fitting for the three major food crops both under traditional and new technol- ogies. The following results should be interpreted with care since not all of the functional forms had a high R2 and significant coefficients. For example rice normative supply functions had a low R2 and insignificant coefficient. The analysis shows that the price elasticities for rice, corn, and cassava are less than one for price ranges up to three times the present price for both traditional and new 184 technologies. Although the normative supply functions for the three major food crops are inelastic in all cases, the normative supply function for cassava is less inelastic. Rice price elasticities are equal under the traditional and new technologies with the existing resource levels. Corn price elasticities are higher under the new technology than under the traditional technology. This is also true for cassava. These results may imply that price increases would be more effective to increase the three major food crops production under the newtechnology. The results of the analysis also show that the price elasticities of the three major food crops are nearly constant even when their prices are tripled. Therefore relative price increases for these food crops as an incentive to increase food production appears likely to be effective for a broad range of prices. 6.2 Policy Implications The policy implications derived from this study are limited to the assumptions made, data reliability, analy- tical framework used, and the construction of the repre- sentative farms. The quantitative estimates of the parameters may differ from their true magnitudes but at least this study has indicated the likely economic effects of the introduction of the new technology on traditional small upland farms in Lampung. To release population pressure in Java, Lampung has a great potential as a transmigration area due to its 185 strategic location and great potential for food crop pro- duction. Large areas still available are not yet farmed in Lampung province. The analysis of a small representative farm (1.38 hectares) in North Lampung which is a relatively newly settled transmigration area shows that there is poten- tial to increase food production and farm income through the adoption of currently available new technology. Therefore, the develOpment of small upland farm in the newly settled area in Lampung would partly tackle the problem of popula- tion distribution, and the problem of increasing food pro- duction and increasing small upland farm income. For Central and South Lampung regions there is limited potential for increasing the output and farm income through the ad0ption of the currently available new tech- nology. Therefore efforts should be emphasized on the production and the introduction of other new technology not currently available such as high yielding varieties, new cropping patterns and new crops. The study also shows that an increase in the avail- ability of labor could enhance the increase in output and farm income in the adoption of the new technology. Hired labor is also limiting since there are no landleSS farmers in the study area. The use of animal draft for land prep- aration could release part of the labor constraints in this peak period as could other sources of power such as trac- tors for land preparation. Other selective simple 186 mechanization of some of the farm operations also need to be considered.. The analysis of the representative farm in Central Lampung, where irrigated rice production was also included in the model, shows that the marginal value product of irri- gated land is much higher than the marginal value product of upland. Therefore it is important to explore the pro- fitability of converting upland into irrigated land to increase both food production and farm income. The planning of agricultural development should be continued toward the expansion of the adoption of the new technology on the small upland farm in the newly settled areas. To facilitate the process of diffusion of the new technology to the small upland farms, a number of programs were needed including research to produce new profitable inputs, farmer training for the use of these new inputs, farmers organization for the distribution of these new inputs and for marketing their agricultural products. The efforts such as of the Tani Makmur Project in this regard need to be continued and expanded. The normative supply functions of the major food crops are inelastic, i.e., at the existing price levels the rice supply price elasticity is about 0.44 both under the traditional and new technologies; corn supply price elas- ticity is 0.37 under the traditional technology and 0.46 under the new technology; and cassava supply price 187 elasticity is 0.50 under the traditional technology and 0.89 under the new technology. The price elasticity of supply of cassava is less inelastic compared to rice and corn both under traditional and new technologies. This may imply that price incentive is more effective to increase cassava production than rice or corn. The response of the output of corn and cassava to a 1 percent increase in their prices is higher under the new technology than under the traditional technology. This may imply that price incentive is relevant to increase food pro- duction in the areas where the new technology have been adopted. The analysis also shows that the increase in the relative price of cassava by 50 percent (from Rp 17 to Rp 20.50 per kilogram, ceteris paribus), has the largest impact on farm income, i.e., an increase of 20 percent. This may imply that the most effective price policy to increase income of the small upland farmers in North Lampung is by increasing the relative price of cassava. 6.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Further Study The effects of technological changes are locational and time specific due to differences in the physical, economic, and institutional environment in which the changes take place. The study only covered a one year crop 188 cycle on the very limited representative areas. For better information of the effects of the new technology on the key farm variables, similar studies are needed on other regions and other cropping years in order to obtain a more compre- hensive picture. The linear programming approach is static in its nature while farming is dynamic. The linear programming approach is also within partial equilibrium conditions. The path of the technological diffusion from one equilibrium to another could not be identified by the static approach. This knowledge is important for policy makers as is the knowledge of the equilibrium conditions. The partial equilibrium conditions assumes that the price of one com- modity can increase while the price of others are kept con- stant. This is an unrealistic situation, especially for crops which are competitive or complement any and supple- mentary in the production process. For example the increase in the price of rice and an increase in its production will compete for the use of land and other resources with the production of corn and cassava. The increase in production of rice may be at the expense of the decrease in land devoted to corn production. As the supply of corn decreases, its price may rise. Hence there is a positive correlation between the rice price and the price of corn. A rise in the price of rice tends to pull the price of the competitive products in the same direction. This condition has obviously violated the analysis in this 189 study, in which the price of one crop was increased while the price of its competitive crops are held constant. The aggregate price effect of the technological changes is not considered. As the aggregate production increases the price of that crop may fall, so the price range used in the normative supply of the major food crops may be unrealistic. Perennial crops such as clove which recently experienced a dramatic increase in price is a strong competitor for land resources. This was not taken into consideration in this study. A study on the farming system which includes the perennial crops is needed. On the input side, the circumstances of the tech- nological change virtually guarantees that well established, well stocked and efficiently functioning input markets for the adoption of the new technology will take a considerable time to establish. Technical information that must accom- pany the sale of the new inputs is rarely possessed by the traditional shopkeeper. This is also not taken into con- sideration in this study. The study does not take into account the distribu- tive effect of the new technology. This is an important study to undertake in order to shed some light on the likely effect of the introduction of the new technology in achiev- ing the equity objective of the government. Development strategies which are based only on economic efficiency may be disastrous in the long run. 190 To overcome the labor constraints in the peak sea- sons, the introduction of alternative sources of power is needed. For this purpose a study of the potential impacts of the alternative forms and level of mechanization on cropping patterns, output, labor and other resource use and productivity, as well as on farm income, is needed. The last but possibly the most important limitation of the study is that the data obtained by interviewing the small number of sample farmers once a month within a half I of a complete cropping cycle depended on the farmer's memory recall. To reduce this problem a larger number of sample farmers and more frequent interviews in a shorter period is needed. For example, future studies may well be designed for once or twice a week interviews covering the whole year of a cropping cycle. This method, called "cost route survey," has been used by some researchers in other devel- oping countries, but has been very rare in Indonesia. Most of the study limitations mentioned are not restricted to the farm planning and supply estimation tech- nique used in this study. Other techniques of farm planning and supply estimates also face similar limitations. Despite these limitations, the study has shed some light on the likely effects of the technological change on the key farm variables of the small upland farm, and has broadened our knowledge concerning the role of the new technology as a strategy for the development of the traditional small upland farm in Lampung. WI‘ um..- APPENDICES APPENDIX A MAPS OF INDONESIA AND LAMPUNG PROVINCE 191 ...-3.5... 835: «I305. 33. 3: a in! a!- H— 02 I!!! ...-3.... la. .3... a 12.-:3 ...—5.3:. 3: In III. 33.3 SI. In ‘0‘! H‘- a In; 82:41: ...-H a a. cap! 8" I 0233 I! .3. H 123-01:! Icicle... 3550 an ..i... in slid fl 8|.- al...‘ In 3:38.. .35!!- 300 a; I: 3: H I!!! .3" 5.0.53 In 2339.3: Ila-gel. ISIS «Ea-18.. :8; I i 88.6.... Small .3133 :53 an :58...- 3325 I Ilsa-I is 12.8 I 42.30 3.0.26... 0 3! .3833 12:! H 1.3-...! ...—1.3 :33 I 8.333 2.313 n g 8...... _.._-.33 .38.. II 8.13 .813 u 939:. Is. :5 a .350 j ..:n\ . .o . 6.....i unadan. icon-Ha c0303.. ‘VHQO t 3§§s o 3600 0303: w . ... I. :33 v.5. J: I .0 I43 .3 .l [a 0 r..\\ \:.(\ K a s) K P It? \\ 1 RCA .. mI-‘PSU I mug-SKA Nd «(L chat: flqufia-E \““\ ‘10“ a . u :1 Ls 35:0 . . . _ 02 z. :0 035:0: .H. - t. . . < m on ma... ....ncS A“. Each _ H .. 0.50.: .3... nI . . H." h It fit IV '04 A \ ’0'” I a. h N) I ‘0 \ FWJ a ...) .I Hi \ \ 192 vI 0..-...“I‘ 0. 53311112351113!!! J, 1 MM!!!“ II M I I l ; Mg 1):!) “m Hm: I '3 :3 ! géémm .. 15w: DIP 383 Inn-lulu- =§ 38“ Cult-...! IAP'IDA “J LAMPUNG APPENDIX B MAJOR FOOD CROP PRODUCTION BY SUBREGIONS OF LAMPUNG I I mmm mv mhm can vaa 00m mmam mom SMHMHHm .ON I I Hon mm Am oo memo momm Homo vomm ammo Hmnsam .mH I I mva new ooH mmH mmoo oomm ssh mom ohm: ocsncme .oH I I oo v mm mm Homm mmmH one mom ochssmx uHxsm .AH o o onH on mm 04 oooo mHoH HooH mHm uHflcmm .0H 4 0 New mo on on oonm oon mmH om zooms .mH mm mm venom nomH ooH moH vmmm ammo mom mam sumomumm .eH mm mm mom oHH oHH on oomm ooHN «50 vom 5:20 cmocmHEmHm .mH mo no omomH Hon 4 o omoH ohm oomm HooH mosamm .mH RoH mom omo mm smH mom moo mom I I saw: omsxm: .HH I I oHH oH «H om oooH «so mwmm mmoH Hnanm: .oH I I «on mm em on boom «HRH moo 0mm mHmomcmz .o I I oono mmom ham mom ooomH oomo HNH Hmocma mcmzmm ocmHze .o I I ommvm meow quH oms Hooo mHmv oNH ms HHoo 0:030: mamHoe .e I I mmoH ooH we om Noam momm oeH om umHmm meocsm .o m o vaH so om mm oon voH oHH oo mumps meocsm .m A NH omHm mom omoH «mmH some ommm «so omm cmumHmm 0:00: .v m m «Home ooom Nmo omsH moom Room HA so HssHe 0:00: .m o o mon mHN mm mm voov omHm moo smm annum 0:000 .m Hm mm monm «oHH ono moo Hoom msoH omm oom Heanmuox .H mCOB mm MSG? ME MCOB mm wCOH. m: MCOB mm :0 08000 :on0H mcm0n>om 0>mmmmu CHOU 00Hm 00Hm u M\ . now ocmHoo oomHon .mhma How mcsmewq nuHoz :H con0HQsm an COHuUDUOHm QOHU 000m Hommzll.am 0HQMB UZDAZdA m0 mZOHOWmmDm Wm ZOHEODQOmm momU OOOm MOhfiz m xHQmemd 193 194 .00:H>oum 0::ms0q mo 90:00: :0H0:0uxm H0H50H50HHO¢ "00H000 Hem mom bmvmvm Hooma oavm mmno mvomm mmmmv oooav mahmH H0009 m v mwa HH 0H om 0mm oom omov mama :0u0H0m mmm .vN I I mma HH OH m NFH om wand N00 0000: mmm .mm I I mom 09 00H 09H mum mum mmvm ®9HH :0m:09 mmm .NN I I OHH 0 0m 0m mmHH 900 mvmv onaa uHxnm xwa0m .HN 0:09 0: 0:09 0: 0:09 0m 0:09 0: 0:09 0: 0:00 90 0>0000 :Ho 00Hm 00H: :000E000M\:0Hm0unnm Q m U U 0:0HQD 0:0H304 .omscHucoOII.Hm mHnms 195 .00:H>oum 0::mEOH mo 90:00: :0H0:00xm H0000H50HHO: "000500 NHHNN o00mm m00H00 Nenmw NHmmv HHmNm 000H0 00000 00000N vomom H0000 NvmoH 0oNNH 0000 000 NoNoH 0000 00NH 0o0H 0m0H 0H0 H0H00 000000 .0N HH 0H vomvN HHmN 00H NHN 0H0 H0: 00 H0 00000000 .000 .mN oN oN oo0HH omsH omN oom onH oovH 0N0: smoH 0H0H0H00 .NN NH mN 0000H mmoH 000 000 HmNH oomH N000 0NOH 0H0: 000000 .HN 0 0H ooHNH 0NOH N00 oNN 0H: 0H: 0NO0H 0N00 E00000: .000 .oN I I 000N0 0000 NeoH 0oHH N000 IImv 00m mvN 0Hnssm .0H 00 omH omHov omeq 0:0 oo0 000N 000H NNov 0ovN ofl000H0M .mH HOH 00N NooNH omHH oo0 oHo 0NH0 ovH0 oHH0 omNm :00: 0:000: .NH I I oMMHN meoH NNN :00 oovv 000N HNNHm 00o0 00000 H00000000 .0H 0H 00 omvH0 0Nm0 HomH NNmH NNNN 0N00 momm mooH 0H0sm 000000 .0H I I omoN omm 0m o0 owe oo0 oNNmN ovnh 00000:: .0H I I H00N 000 N0 N0 mmmH N0oN oHONN mom0 00:0: .000 .HH I I 0000N moom 00H mom 0H0 00N 000 0N0 x0000m .000 .NH I I N000 0H0 0 0 HHO NHq eanH meHm 00000 00:0: .HH I I 000: Ho0 0H 0N 00H on HHO0H momm o00cHHoHHs: .oH 000HH msoHH mH0N 00H H00mH oN00 NH00H 000: m00m 0:0H 000000 .0 0o0N No00 oomMN 0NmH onoH 0000 mnnm 00H0 H000 0000 H0000H00z .00H .0 I I omHo 000 HOHH 000 Novm 000N 0:00 >00N 000000 >03 .0 N 0 onmov meow Hnmm 0o0m HNHH 00Nm omvH 000 00000000 .0 mnHN om0m N0H0H No0H 0oN NNH 000 :00 H000 0NmN :00coH0xm: .0 :00 000 HommH >00 0N0H N00H 000H mmNH 00N0 o00N 0000:0000 .0 0N 00 somHH 0:0 omH 0HN mm0H msN HH00H 0H00 0000000000 .0 I I «om 00 0 A om 0 HNoHN Amos onussHue .N 0 0 ooos 0o: 0o: 000 000 NNN msmmH 0000 0000: .H 0:09 0: 0:09 0m 0:09 0: 0:09 0: 0:09 0: 00a: 00H: :0005000M\:0Hmmun:m 0:00Q>Om 0>0000U :HOU . . 0:0Hmo 0:0H304 .wnma How m::mE0H H000:0U :H :oflm0unom >0 :ofluosooum @000 0009 Hom0ZII.Nm 0Hn09 196 .00:0>000 0::QEMQ 00 00:00: :000:00xm H0050H90000¢ "mousom Hmoa mmma mmmmom 0HNON vaoa 00mm mochm maoam hvhmoa mmham H0009 I I 000H NOH 0N 0m mmoa N00 000a 0N0 memnnzxaU .ON 00 omH vmmm mmH H0 m0 000m aqua momva @000 onomo:03 .0H I I om m CH m end 00 mmmma Hmmw 0:a0¢ 000M .ma I I 0H®N ovm omm mom ommm omha mawv mo0a 0:500:00 Sufism .ba I I 00m mm vow mmm ovm ovm omooa mmmm 0:00000:0Hm9 .oH om om 00mm mod Hma ova mhma 0mm mmoHH 000m :000H00mm .mH mod mom mvwm 0mm mam mom woma 0N0 mmmm vaa omuwsoxnm .vH I I I I I I I I 0000H 0000 030000000 .0H I I N00 00 I I I I 000HH H000 0000000000 .NH I I muoa 00H H0 00 000 N00 0mhm mmvm mxzmmvmm .HH I I mom om m0 m0 comm coma 0m00a 000m 0:00:000M .OH 0m mm mamo mam mmma mum 00mm ooom womaa omam :00009 .00 .0 00H avm momma onH mmmm mmma 00mm 00mm mmam moam 00002 .m 00 00 mommma mvmma 00m on 00mm m0om 0NHm NO0H :oumvmx .0 ma ma 0mm 0m mm 00 Hmmw mmvm 000m 00nd :05000 .00 .0 0m 00 000m 00H Nmm Nov boom ooom mvaa 0mv 0:500m .9 .m mvm 0m0 00mm mama omhm vmvm vOMvH mmob 00mm 000m 0:5nwumx .0 I I 0mm 00 N0 mm mma ow 0mov omma 00:00H0M .m 00 00 @0000 0mm 000 How omom oooa mmom mmmH :0:00:0:0m .N ma 0H 0m00 omo 00m mma Nomm mama onNH mmmm mmamm .H 0:09 0m 0:09 mm 0:09 mm 0:09 mm 0:09 mm :0 05000 :00000 0:00:000 0>00000 :000 000m 000m 0 M\ . 99m 0:0HQD 0:0H304 .mhma Mom 0::QEMA £0500 :0 :0000039m an :000090000 0000 HOnMZII.mm 0Hn09 APPENDIX C EXPLANATION OF ABBREVIATIONS USED IN CROPPING PATTERNS OF THE REPRESENTATIVE FARMS IN LAMPUNG APPENDIX C EXPLANATION OF ABBREVIATIONS USED IN CROPPING PATTERNS OF THE REPRESENTATIVE FARMS IN LAMPUNG Cropping Patterns/ Abbreviations Explanations C+ULR¥CV ULRfCV ULR CV LLR ULR-SB C+SB¥CV Corn and upland rice planted at the same time/or within a week and cassava planted one month later on the same piece of land. Upland rice and cassava planted on the same piece of land but cassava planted a month later after rice. Upland rice as a pure stand, only one crop a year. Cassava planted as a sole crop, only one crop a year. Lowland rice as a sole crop planted in fully or partly irrigated land. Two crops a year is usually the practice. Upland rice and soybeans planted on the same piece of land, but soybeans planted after upland rice harvested. Corn and soybeans planted at the same time/or within a week and one month later cassava planted on the same piece of land. 197 198 Cropping Patterns/ Abbreviations Explanations C+ULR/CV SB-SB-SB/CV C/COC GNDT PEP CfCV ULR-SB/COC COF+COC CLO+COC COC/FC COF/FC PEP+CLO Corn and upland rice planted at the same time or within a week and after one month cassava planted surrounding each block of land where corn and upland rice planted. Three crops of soybeans planted in sequence, after one crop harvested the second crop planted and the third soybean crop planted after the second crop harvested. Cassava was planted a month later after the first crop planted surrounding every block of land. Corn is planted between coconut trees. Groundnut as a sole crop. Pepper (perennial) crop as a sole crop. Cassava is planted after one month later after corn planted on the same piece of land. After upland rice harvested then soybeans planted and these two crops were planted between coconut trees. Coffee and coconut both are peren- nial crops planted together on the same piece of land arranged in rows. Clove planted between coconut trees. Food crops were planted between coconut trees. Some food crops planted between coffee trees. Pepper and clove planted together on the same piece of land. 199 Cropping Patterns/ Abbreviations Explanations CLO/PC ' Some food crops were planted between clove trees. APPENDIX D EXPLANATION OF ABBREVIATIONS USED IN THE LINEAR PROGRAMMING TABLE OF THE REPRE- SENTATIVE FARMS IN LAMPUNG APPENDIX D EXPLANATION OF ABBREVIATIONS USED IN THE LINEAR PROGRAMMING TABLE OF THE REPRE- SENTATIVE FARMS IN LAMPUNG Row No./ Column No. Abbreviations Complete Headings Restrictions 1. Land Land operated/under cultivation 2. FLXAUG Family Labor in August 3. FLXSEP Family Labor in September 4. FLXOCT Family Labor in October 5. FLXNOV Family Labor in November 6. FLXDEC Family Labor in December 7. FLXJAN Family Labor in January 8. FLXFEB Family Labor in February 9. FLXMAR Family Labor in March 10. FLXAPR Family Labor in April 11. FLXMAY Family Labor in May 12. FLXJUN Family Labor in June 13. FLXJUL Family Labor in July 14. HLXAUG Hired Labor in August 15. HLXSEP Hired Labor in September 16. HLXOCT Hired Labor in October 17. HLXNOV Hired Labor in November 18. HLXDEC Hired Labor in December 19. HLXJAN Hired Labor in January 20. HLXFEB Hired Labor in February 21. HLXMAR Hired Labor in March 200 Row No./ Column No. Abbreviations Complete Headings 22." HLXAPR Hired Labor in April 23. HLXMAY Hired Labor in May 24. HLXJUN Hired Labor in June 25. HLXJUL Hired Labor in July 26. AHXAUG Animal Hired in August 27. AHXSEP Animal Hired in September 28. AHXOCT Animal Hired in October 29. AHXNOV Animal Hired in November 30. SEEDRC Quantity of Rice Seed Used 31. SEEDXC Quantity of Corn Seed Used 32. SEEDSB Quantity of Soybean Seed Used 33. SEEDCV Quantity of Cassava Stick Used 34. FERTXN Quantity of Fertilizer-N Used 35. FERTXP Quantity of Fertilizer-P Used 36. INSECTD Quantity of Insecticides Used 37. OCXAUG Operating Capital in August 38. OCXSEP Operating Capital in September 39. OCXOCT Operating Capital in October 40. OCXNOV Operating Capital in November 41. OCXDEC Operating Capital in December 42. OCXJAN Operating Capital in January 43. OCXFEB Operating Capital in February 44. OCXMAR Operating Capital in March 45. OCXAPR Operating Capital in April 46. OCXMAY Operating Capital in May 47. OCXJUN Operating Capital in June 48. OCXJUL Operating Capital in July 49. OPTRICE Quantity of Rice Produced 50. OPTCORN Quantity of Corn Produced 51. OPTSOBN Quantity of Soybeans Pro- duced 202 CgifimgoNo. Abbreviations Complete Headings 52.- OPTCASV Quantity of Cassava Pro- duced 53. CONSRICE Minimum Quantity of Rice for Household Consumption 54. CONSCORN Minimum Quantity of Corn for Household Consumption 55. CONSCASV Minimum Quantity of ' Cassava for Household Consumption 56. AMT-BC Total Amount Borrowed 57. LMT HL-AUG Limited Hired Labor Available in August 58. LMT HL-SEP Limited Hired Labor Available in September 59. LMT HL-OCT Limited Hired Labor Available in October 60. LMT HL-NOV Limited Hired Labor Available in November 61. LMT HL-DEC Limited Hired Labor Available in December 62. LMT HL-JAN Limited Hired Labor Available in January 63. LMT HL-FEB Limited Hired Labor Available in February 64. LMT HL-MAR Limited Hired Labor Available in March 65. LMT HL-APR Limited Hired Labor Available in April 66. LMT HL-MAY Limited Hired Labor Available in May 67. LMT HL-JUN Limited Hired Labor Available in June 68. LMT HL-JUL Limited Hired Labor Available in July 69. LMT AH-AUG Limited Hired Animal Available in August 70. LMT AH-SEP Limited Hired Animal Available in September 71. LMT AH-OCT Limited Hired Animal Available in October 72. LMT AH-NOV Limited Hired Animal Available in November 73. LMT BCAUG Limited Borrowed Capital in August 74. LMT BCSEP Limited Borrowed Capital in September 203 Row No./ Column No. Abbreviations Complete Headings 75. 76. 77. 78. 79. 80. 81. 82. 83. 84. LMT BCOCT LMT BCNOV LMT BCDEC LMT BCJAN LMT BCFEB LMT BCMAR LMT BCAPR LMT BCMAY LMT BCJUN LMT BC JUL Limited Borrowed Capital in October Limited Borrowed Capital in November Limited Borrowed Capital in December Limited Borrowed Capital in January Limited Borrowed Capital in February Limited Borrowed Capital in March Limited Borrowed Capital in April Limited Borrowed Capital in May Limited Borrowed Capital in June Limited Borrowed Capital in July Activities 1. AlC+ULRfCV A2C+ULR¥CV A3C+ULR¥CV A4C+ULR¥CV (TTl) (TT2) (NTl) (NTZ) A5ULR+CV (TT) Produce Corn, Upland Rice and Cassava in Mixture with Manual Labor for Land Preparation Produce Corn, Upland Rice and Cassava in Mixture with Animal Power for Land Preparation Produce Corn, Upland Rice and Cassava in Mixture with Use of Fertilizer Level 1 and Use of Insecticides as Recommended. Produce Corn, Upland Rice and Corn in Mixture with Use of Fertilizers Level 2 with Use of Insecticides at Recommended Level Produce Upland Rice and Cassava with Traditional Technology 204 Row No./ Column No. Abbreviations Complete Headings 10. ll. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. A6ULR+VC (NT) A7C+CV (TTl) A8C+CV (TT2) A9C+CV (NT) A10ULR-SBT AllULR-SBN AlZCVTTl A13CVTT2 A14CVNT AlSHLXAUG A16HLXSEP Produce Upland Rice and Cassava in Mixture with the Use of Fertilizers (New Technology) Produce Corn and Cassava in Mixture with Manual Labor for Land Prepara- tion and no Use of New Inputs (Traditional Technology) Produce Corn and Cassava in Mixture with Animal Power for Land Prepara- tion, no Use of New * Inputs (Traditional Technology) Produce Corn and Cassava in Mixture with the Use of the New Inputs (New Technology) Produce Upland Rice and Soybeans in Sequence with no Use of New Inputs (Traditional Technology) Produce Upland Rice and Soybeans in Sequence with Use of New Inputs (New Technology) Produce Cassava with Manual Labor for Land Preparation, no Use of New Inputs (Traditional Technology) Produce Cassava with Animal Power for Land Preparation, no Use of New Inputs (Traditional Technology) Produce Cassava with the Use of New Inputs (New Technology Hiring Labor Activities in August Hiring Labor Activities in September 205 ngzmgofié. Abbreviations Complete Headings 17. A17HLXOCT Hiring Labor Activities in October 18. AlBHLXNOV Hiring Labor Activities in November 19. A19HLXDEC Hiring Labor Activities in December 20. A20HLXJAN Hiring Labor Activities in January 21. AZlHLXFEB Hiring Labor Activities in February 22. A22HLXMAR Hiring Labor Activities in March 23. A23HLXAPR Hiring Labor Activities in April 24. A24HLXMAY Hiring Labor Activities in May 25. A25HLXJUN Hiring Labor Activities in June 26. A26HLXJUL Hiring Labor Activities in July 27. A27AHXAUG Hiring Animal for Land Preparation in August 28. A28AHXSEP Hiring Animal for Land Preparation in September 29. A29AHXOCT Hiring Animal for Land Preparation in September 30. A30AHXNOV Hiring Animal for Land Preparation in November 31. A31BFERT-N Buying Fertilizer Activ- ities in October 32. A32BFERT—P Buying Fertilizer Activ- ities in October 33. A33BPSTD Buying Insecticide Activ- ities in October 34. A34BRCXSEP Buying Rice Activities for Consumption in September 35. A35BRCXOCT Buying Rice Activities for Consumption in October 36. A36BRCXNOV Buying Rice Activities for Consumption in November 37. A37BRCXDEC Buying Rice Activities for Consumption in December 206 Row No./ Column No. Abbreviations Complete Headings 38.’ A38BRCXJAN Buying Rice Activities for Consumption in January 39. A39BOYXFEB Buying Oyek Activities for Consumption in February 40. A40BOYXMAR Buying Oyek Activities for Consumption in March 41. A41CONSRICE Family Household Rice Consumption 42. A42CONSCORN Family Household Corn Consumption 43. A43CONSCASV Family Household Cassava Consumption 44. A44SRCMAY Selling Rice Activities in May 45. A45 SCMAR Selling Corn Activities in March 46. A4GSSBFEB Selling Soybeans Activ- ities in February 47. A47SCVSEP Selling Cassava Activ- ities in September 48. A480RCTOSSRC Rice Seed from Own Pro- duction 49. A49OCTOSSC Corn Seed from Own Pro- duction 50. ASOOSBTOSSB Soybean Seed from Own Production 51. A51FL/NOVTOSSCV Family Labor Activities in November to Produce Cassava Sticks 52. ASZBCAUG Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in August 53. A53BCSEP Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in September 54. A54BCOCT Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in October 55. A55BCNOV Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in November 56. A56BCDEC Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in December 57. A57BCJAN Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in January 58. ASBBCFEB Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in February 207 CEIEmHONo. Abbreviations Complete Headings 59. A59BCMAR Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in March 60. A60BCAPR Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in April 61. A61BCMAY Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in May 62. A62BCJUN Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in June 63. A63BCJUL Borrowing Capital Activ- ities in July 64. A64TC-AS Transfer Capital from August to September 65. A65TC-SO Transfer Capital from September to October 66. A66TC-ON Transfer Capital from October to November 67. A67TC-ND Transfer Capital from November to December 68. A68TC-DJ Transfer Capital from December to January 69. A69TC-JF Transfer Capital from January to February 70. A70TC-FM Transfer Capital from February to March 71. A71TC-MA Transfer Capital from March to April 72. A72TC-AM Transfer Capital from April to May 73. A73TC—MJ Transfer Capital from May to June 74. A74TC-JJ Transfer Capital from June to July 75. A75PY OFF Pay Off Activities in July APPENDIX E MONTHLY MAJOR FOOD CROPS PRICES AT THE NEAREST MARKET TO THE REPRESENTATIVE FARMS IN LAMPUNG oam cam cam mew mew mmm mom mmm mmm mmm hmm mam cmmnwom .m mm mm om om om om ma ma ma ma m n w>mmmmu .v oaa oaa oHH OHH oaa mad OHH mm mm mm em on cuoo .m oaa oaa OHH OHH OHH OHH mod ooa mm mm ooa OOH mowm owaasnco .m mam mam mam cam cam mmm oom mna mna mna oma mha mowm pmaasm .H cmumawm memcnm .H omo >oz poo mom msfi How can >82 Ham Hm: bum coo mmfluflooafiou on\mm. moflum manucoz mowum>< cam uoauumflonsm *.mhma MOM .mcomfimq susomv OmHmnoxam ocm.Amc:mqu cunozv cmumamm memcsm CH mmOAHm mono boom Mono: manucozlu.am manna UZDQZflA ZH wzmflm W>HB afloawoé How mumospoum How umxumfi umwummc mzu ma oflumcoxnm .Amcsmemq suuoz. mmmaafl> mmuwxmume HOm umxuma m.umosooum ummumm: may we cmumamm flmxmcsm« .memmcoocH .ocsmfimq mo >ocmm¢ coflmcwuxm amusuHsOAHm< "mousom mam cam com mum mum mum mum mum omm com com mmm cmwnmow .m mm mm om ma mm om ma ha ma ma ma NH m>mmmmu .v OHH OHH OHH OHH moa mm ms ms mu om om Hm cuoo .m ooa OOH ooa ooa ooa 00H mm mm om co mm mm oofim pmaasncb .N com mom mom mom com com com mud mma oma moa 05H moafi pmaasm .H onumnoxsm .HH own >oz poo mom wad ado can wmz Had no: Dom coo AOM\mmv moaum wanucoz momuw>¢ mmfluHQOEEoo cam vowuumflvnam .omscwucooln.am manna BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Agrawal, R. C. and Heady, E. O. (1972) Operation Research Methods for Agricultural Decisions. The Iowa State University Press, Ames. Ahmed, A. Raji (1972) The Human Factors and Its Effect on Size of Farm- ing Operation. Agricultural Economic Series, No. 127, University of Idaho. Anderson, J. C. and Heady, E. O. (1965) Normative Supply Functions and Optimal Plans for Northeastern Iowa. Iowa Agricultural and Home Economics Experiment Station Research Bulletin, No. 537. Andrews, M. S. and John, R. M. (1976) An Integrated Production-Consumption Farm Model for Dominican Republic. Agricultural Experiment Station, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland. Arifin, Sultoni (1978) The Effect of Village Labor Resource on the Feasi- bility of the New Cropping System in Indonesia. M. Sc. Thesis, University of Philippine, Los Banos (Unpublished). ‘ Asian Development Bank (1978) Key Indicators of Developing Member Countries of ADB, Vol. IX, No. 1. Bachtiar, Nurzaman (1978) Cash Liquidity in the Adoption of New Cropping System in Central Lampung, Indonesia. M. Sc. (Agric. Ec.) University of Philippine, Los Banos (Unpublished). Buckwell, A. E. and Hazell, P. B. R. (1972) Implications of Aggregation Bias for the Construc- tion of Static and Dynamic Linear Programming Supply Models. Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 119-134. 210 10. ll. 12. l3. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 211 Burt, Oscar R. (1964) Curve Fitting to Step Functions. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 46, No. 3, pp. 662-673. Carter, Harold O. (1963) Representative Farm--Guide for Decision Making. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 45, pp. 1458-1468. Central Bureau of Statistics, Jakarta, Indonesia (1979) Statistical Pocket Book of Indonesia 1977/78. Central Bureau of Statistics, Jakarta, Indonesia. Central Research Institute for Agriculture (1977) Cropping System Research (Indramayu and Lampung). Annual Report 1976-1977. Central Research Insti- tute for Agriculture, Bogor, Indonesia. Collier, William £3 21. (1973) Recent Changes in Rice Harvesting System in Java. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies. Austral- ian National University, Canberra. Collinson, M. P. (1974) Some Guidelines for Farm Economic Data Collection in Rural Areas of Africa. Agricultural Develop- ment Seminar, Beirut (mimeo). Crawford, E. W.; C. Lassister; and R. A. Milligan (1977) The Usefulness of Poly-period Linear Programming for Farm Management Analysis in Developing Countries. Agric. Econ. Dept. Mimeo No. 77-35. Cornell University, Ithaca. Davis, Gloria (1979) Draft Working Paper on Transmigration in Indonesian Program. World Bank (Unpublished). Dillon, J. and Anderson, J. (1971) Allocative Efficiency in Traditional Agriculture and Risk. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 53, pp. 26-32. Dixon, John (1979) Production and Consumption of Cassava in Indonesia. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. XV, No. 3. Djauhari, Aman (1977) Cropping Patterns in Indramayu and Central Lampung Areas: Results of Baseline Survey, Department of Social Economic Research, Central Research Insti- tute for Agriculture, Bogor, Indonesia. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 212 Eckert, Jerry B. (1977) Farmers Response to High Yielding Wheat in Pakis- tan's Punjab. In Tradition and Dynamics in Small Farm Agriculture, edited by R. D. Stevens. Food and Agricultural Organization (1976) National Method of Collecting Agricultural Sta- tistics, Asia and Far East, Bangkok. Friedrich, K. H. (1977) Farm Management Data Collection and Analysis. Food and Agricultural Organization, Agricultural Services Bulletin No. 34, Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome, pp. 70-81. Garnaut, Ross (1979) Survey of Recent Developments Summary. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. XV, No. 2, Australian National University. Glassburner, Bruce (1978) Survey of Recent Development. Bulletin of Indo- nesian Economic Studies, Vol. XV, No. 2, Austral- ian National University. Gotsch, C. N. and Falcon, W. P. (1975) The Green Revolution and Economics of Punjab Agriculture. Food Research Institute Studies, Vol. XIV, No. l. Harsh, Stephen B. and Black, Roy J. (1975) Agricultural Economics Linear Programming Package Version 2, A. E. Staff Paper No. 75-10, Michigan State University. Heady, E. 0. £3 a1. (1961) Agricultural Supply Functions--Estimating Tech- niques and Interpretations. Iowa State Univer- sity Press, Ames, U.S.A. Heady, E. O. and Candler, W. (1973) Linear Programming Methods. Iowa State University Press Heyer, J. (1971) A Linear Programming Analysis of Constraints on Peasant Farmers in Kenya. Food Research Institute Studies, Vol. 10, No. l. Hopper, W. D. (1965) Allocation Efficiency in Traditional Indian Agriculture. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47, No. 3, pp. 611-624. ‘IL 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 38. 39. 40. 41. 213 Hopper, W. D. (1979) Indonesia, the Awakening Giants. A Supplement to Euro Money, January 1979. Japan Overseas Technical Cooperation Agency (1972) Report of the Japanese Implementation Survey MissiOn for Agricultural Development in Lampung, Indonesia. Johnston, B. F. and Mellor, J. W. (1961) The Role of Agriculture in Economic DevelOpment. American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp. 566-593. Jones, W. O. (1978) Cassava in Indonesia: Preliminary Observation, Jakarta, Indonesia. Kennedy, J. O. S. and Francisco, E. M. (1974) On the Formulation of Risk Constraints of Linear Programming. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 25, No. 2. (1977) Kongress Agronomi 1977: Agronomi Menjawab Tantangan 2000, Jakarta, Indonesia. Kottke, M. (1967) Anatomy of Step Supply Functions. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 107-117. Krenz, R. D. gt El- (1960) Profit Maximizing Plans and Static Supply Schedules for Fluid Milk in Des Moines Milk Shed. Iowa Agricultural and Home Economics Experiment Station Research Bulletin, No. 416. (1962) Normative Supply Functions by Linear Programming Procedures. Agricultural Economic Research, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 13-18. Lee, Sang M. (1976) Linear Organization for Management. Petrocelli/ Charter, New York. Low, A. R. C. (1974) Decision Taking Under Uncertainty: A Linear Pro— gramming Model of Peasant Farmer Behavior. Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. XXV, No. 3, pp. 311-322. 42. 43. 44. 45. 46. 47. 48. 49. 50. 51. 214 Lynch, Frank (1976) Field Data Collection in Developing Countries: Experiences in Asia. Seminar Report No. 4, Agricultural Development Council, Inc., New York. McCarl, B. A. (1978) Indonesian Supply Food Prospects for Food Crops, A Farm Level Linear Programming Analysis of Dryland and Wetland Food Crop Production. World Bank (Unpublished). McIntosh, Jerry L. and Effendi Suryatna (1976) Cropping Systems and Management Practices for Red-Yellow Podzolic Soils. Central Research Institute for Agriculture, Bogor, Indonesia. McNamara, Robert S. (1972) Address to the Board of Governors, Nairobi, Kenya World Bank, Washington, D.C., p. 14. Mellor, J. W. (1967) Toward a Theory of Agricultural Development. In H. R. Southworth and B. F. Johnston (Eds.), Agricultural Development and Economic Growth. New York, Cornell University Press. Miller, Thomas A. and Nauheim, Charles W. (1964) Linear Programming Applied to Cost Minimizing Farm Management Strategies. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 46, No. 3, pp. 556-566. Miller, Thomas A. (1966) Sufficient Conditions for Exact Aggregation in Linear Programming Model. Agricultural Economic Research, Vol. XVIII, No. 2. Moscardi, E. and Allan De Janvry (1977) Attitudes Toward Risk Among Peasants, An Econo- metric Approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 59, pp. 710-716. Mudahar, M. S. (1974) Dynamic Analysis of Direct and Indirect Implica- tion of Technological Change in Agriculture: The Case of Punjab, India. Occasional Paper No. 79, Department of Agricultural Economics, Cornell University. Nainy, A. Kirom gt El- (1979) Cassava Marketing System in Lampung. Central Research Institute for Agriculture, Bogor, Indonesia (Unpublished). 52. 53. 54. 55. 56. 57. 58. 59. 60. 61. 215 Nie, Norman H. gt El. (1975) SPSS: Statistical Package for Social Sciences. McGraw Hill Book Company, New York. Norman, David W. (1973) Economic Analysis of Agricultural Production and Labour Utilization Among the Hausa in the Northern Nigeria. African Rural Employment Paper, No. 4, Michigan State University. Nurdin, Thamrin (1978) Cash Liquidity in the Adoption of New Cropping System in Central Lampung, Indonesia. M. Sc. (Agric. Econ.) University of Philippine, Los Banos (Unpublished). Parhusip, Uben (1976) Supply and Demand Analysis of Rice in Indonesia (1950-1972). M.S. Research Paper, Michigan State University (Unpublished). Prabowo, Dibyo (1978) Water Development and Farm Production Possi- bilities in the Solo River Basin, Central Java, Indonesia: A Linear Programming Analysis. Ph.D. Dissertation, Washington State University (Unpublished). Plaxico, J. S. and Tweeten, L. G. (1963) Representative Farm for Policy and Projection Research. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 45, No. 5, pp. 1458-1468. Ruttan, V. W. and Hayami Yujiro (1971) Strategies for Agricultural Development and Comment by G. L. Beckford. Food Research Institute Studies, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp. 129-148. Schultz, T. W. (1964) Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Yale University. Sheehy, S. J. and McAlexander, R. H. (1964) Selection of Representative Benchmark Farms for Supply Estimation. Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47, No. 3, pp. 681-695. Spencer, Dunstan S. C. (1972) Micro Level Farm Management and Production Economic Research Among Traditional African Farmers: Lesson from Sierra Leone. African Rural Employment Paper, No. 3, Michigan State University. 62. 63. 64. 65. 66. 67. 68. 69. 70. 216 Stevens, R. D. (1977) Tradition and Dynamics in Small Farm Agriculture. Economic Studies in Asia, Africa, and Latin America. The Iowa State University Press, Ames, pp. vii-viii. Sturgess, N. H. and Wijaya Hesti (1979) Land Leasing in East Java. Bulletin of Indo- nesian Economic Studies, Vol. XI, No. 2. (1979) The Third Five Year Development Plan for Agri- cultural Sector, Lampung Province, Book III. Timmer, Peter C. (1971) Estimating Rice Consumption. Bulletin of Indo— nesian Economic Studies, Vol. VII, No. 2, Department of Economics, Research School of Pacific Studies, Australian National University, Canberra. Tsurumi, Yoshi (1977) Transformation of Mitsugoro Pilot Farm. Lampung Report No. 4 (Unpublished). Upton, M. (1974) Some of the Problems in Using Planning Technique. Development Study, No. 14. Reading. Wardhani, Mohammad A. (1974) Toward Rational Farm Plan for Land Settlement in Indonesia: A Study of Land Development Using Linear Programming and Simulation Technique. M. Sc. Thesis, Australian National University (Unpub- lished). Winch III, Fred E. (1976) Costs and Returns of Alternatives Rice Production Systems in Northern Ghana, Implication for Output, Employment, and Income Distribution. Ph.D. Dis- sertation, Michigan State University (unpublished). Woglin, J. (1975) Resource Allocation and Risk: A Case Study on Smallholder Agriculture in Kenya. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 57, pp. 622-630. 217 71. (1974) Workshop on the Development Strategies for Small Farmers. National Agricultural Economic Research Institutes, Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Republic of Korea (Unpublished). 72; Yang, w. Y. (1965) Methods of Farm Management Investigation for Improving Farm Productivity. Agricultural Development Paper No. 80, Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy.