ABSTRACT A SIMULATION ANALYSIS OF PLANNED DAIRY FARM DEVELOPMENT IN EASTERN QUEBEC BY Robert St-Louis Serious criticisms concerning the use of public funds for regional development programs in Eastern Quebec suggested the need for this study. Among the proposed major regional programs were a number of dairy development strategies. The consequences of these strategies at the farm level were chosen as the primary objective of thisfithesis. Towards this end the study included an investigation of the current problem situation in the dairy subsector and an appraisal of various policy alternatives for increasing profitability of dairy enterprises in the area. In the first part of this study, the planning issues in the dairy subsector were examined. A series of factors combine to create a serious low productivity and income problem in dairying in Eastern Quebec. These factors were (1) limited supply of highly productive resources, (2) lack of growth of effective demand for milk, (3) limited job opportunities outside of farming in the region, and (4) poor performance of both the dairy processing industry and the dairy input suppliers. Increases in resource productivity were singled out as a major possible source of increasing income from dairying. Associated with this, however, is the fact that large quantities of resources (especially human resources) now committed to dairying would be forced to shift to Robert St-Louis .~ other uses. From the standpoint of regional agricultural planning, the area where information most seriously falls short of the needs was shown to be with respect to milk demand projections. The sedond part of this thesis analysed alternative regional dairy strategies. These included (1) the establishment of specialized dairy replacement stock farms, (2) improved feeding practices, and (3) farm consolidation and community pasture programs. Additional alternatives considered were (4) subsidizing replacement purchases and (5) artificial insemination. The focus was to compare these alternative strategies from the farmers' point of view. This was done in two steps; first, by analysing field data on dairymen's intentions concerning the various alternatives, and second, through use of a simulation model to project changes in net cash income and cow productivity on two synthesized farms. Primary data from a survey conducted in the area were used. The analysis of the respondents' intentions indicated the following. Mbst dairymen recognized that limited availability of good quality feed was a serious problem in the region. A major concern of the majority was improving the producing capacity of their cows. There was disagreement, however, as to whether artificial insemination might be more appropriate than purchasing replacements to increase the supply of more productive cows. The simulation experiments provided the following results. Those based on low feeding rates indicated that limited availability of good quality feed may be an important factor accounting for low dairy farming inéome. Those simulated under improved feeding rates, to the contrary, Robert St-Louis showed some potentials for increasing income from dairying. On the basis of the present value of cash flows discounted at 6 per cent, A.I. was found to rank first on both the large and the small simulated enterprises, but only by a slight margin over purchased replacements for the larger farm. The practice of buying replacements appears, however, to require more capital than other herd improvement practices. The major policy implications emerging from the study were the following. If policy makers chose to promote buying replacements, increased credit may be a major associated need. Since regional dairymen have strong preferences for raising their own replacements, additional incentives might be required to make them shift to buying replacements. If greatly increased promotion is seriously considered, the returns to this development strategy could be evaluated by benefit-cost analysis. With respect to future research the following issues appear important; (1) analysis of the development potentials of dairying in other areas of Canada as compared to Eastern Quebec, (2) the impact of recent milk supply restrictions on regional dairying, (3) the effects of collective bargaining on the distribution of the rewards for increased productivity in the industry and (4) the likely effects of various planning strategies on the regional milk supply and demand balance. A SIMULATION ANALYSIS OF PLANNED DAIRY FARM DEVELOPMENT IN EASTERN QUEBEC By Robert St-Louis A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1970 C) k;\ *S‘\ ~40 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The author wishes to express his appreciation to the members of his Guidance Committee: Dr. Robert D. Stevens, Dr. M. L. Hayenga, Dr. M. Steinmueller and Dr. J. H. Stapleton for their assistance during his graduate program at Michigan State University. Special thanks are given to the author's Thesis Committee: Dr. R.D. Stevens, Dr. M.L. Hayenga and Dr. C.R. Hoglund for their guidance, advice and encouragement in the development and preparation of this research project. Appreciation is also extended to the Conseil des Recherches Agricoles du Québec for the financial assistance which made possible this portion of my education. Mbst of all, the author is especially indebted to his wife, Renee, for her assistance, interest and encouragement during his graduate program. She has, in addition, contributed many hours at the typewriter. Any errors or omissions found in this manuscript are solely the responsibility of the author. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ii TABLE OF CONTENTS iii LIST OF TABLES vi LIST OF FIGURES x LIST OF APPENDICES xi CHAPTER I. Introduction 1 General Problem Situation 1 Importance 4 Objectives 5 Methodology and Sources of Information 6 Organization of Thesis 7 Part I. Regional Planning in Canada: The Case of Eastern Quebec 9 II. Emergence of Economic Planning in Canada 9 The Meaning of Development Planning 10 On the Role of Planning 11 Planning in Canada 13 The Need for Using Project Appraisal Criteria in Canada 16 Agricultural Planning in a Canadian Perspective 20 Summary 23 III. The General Planning Problems and Objectives in Eastern Quebec 25 Definition of the Region 25 Major Resource Problems in Agriculture 33 iii TABLE.)F CONTENTS (continued) CHAPTER The Causes of the Low Income Problem in Regional Agriculture Lack of Growth of Effective Demand Limited Employment Opportunities Outside Farming Slow Rate of Adoption of Modern Technology The Combined Effects Planning Alternatives Considered by the Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Québec Summary IV. Planning Issues in the Dairy Subsector of Eastern Quebec Problems of the Dairy Subsector in Eastern Quebec The Dairy Processing Industry Farms Producing Milk in Eastern Quebec The Suppliers of Dairy Farming Inputs Long Run Objectives and Comparative Advantage Economic Rationality in the Regional Dairy Subsector Government Activity on the Milk Market On the Dynamics of Resource Adjustments: A Summary Part II. Analysis of Alternative Regional Dairy Development Strategies V. Alternative Dairy Development Strategies and Farmers' Intentions Introduction Alternative Dairy Development Strategies The Regional Dairy Farmers"£ntentions Factors Associated with the Respondents' Preferences Summary VI. Model and Data Used for Simulated Experiments On Simulation Description of the Model System Specifications iv Page 45 45 46 47 48 48 52 54 54 54 64 83 88 97 106 118 124 124 124 126 133 142 149 152 152 156 162 TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued) CHAPTER Assumption of This Thesis Data Used in Simulated Experiments Summary VII. Micro and Macro Implications of Alternative Strategies Criteria for Evaluating Alternative Regional Dairy Development Strategies The Farm Level Resultscf Alternative Strategies Trend Projections Projections under New Program Strategies The Ranking of Alternative Strategies Effects of Various Strategies on Capital Requirements Validity of the Mbdel and Its Results Strengths and Weaknesses of the Model Sensitivity Analysis Issues in the Economic Appraisal of Alternative Strategies Aggregation Issues Problems Related to_the Evaluation of Labor The Income Distribution Problem Regional Milk Supply and Demand Balance Summary Part III. General Summaryiand Policy Implications VIII. Summary and Conclusions Policy Implications Further Research Needs Page 168 172 192 195 195 196 197 200 207 210 212 215 219 228 230 232 233 235 237 240 240 244 245 TABLE 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. LIST OF TABLES The Importance of Economic Sectors in Eastern Quebec Based on Employment. 1963. Population of Eastern Quebec. 1901 to 1966, and Distribution of the Regional Population in Urban, Rural-Farm and Rural Non-Farm, 1951 to 1966. Number of Farms per Zone, and Rate of Disappearance of Farms, 1961 to 1966. Total Number of Farms and Number of Commercial Farms per Zone, 1966. Percentage Distribution of Population by Twenty-Year Age Groups in Eastern Quebec and in all Other Areas of the Province of Quebec, 1966. Value of Agricultural Products Sold by Eastern Quebec Farmers, by Groups of Products, 1965. All Census Farms and Census Farms not Reporting Sales of Dairy Products, Eastern Quebec, 1965. Estimates of the Number of Farms by Classes of Annual Net Farm Income, Eastern Quebec, 1965. Summary of Cost Allocation of Development Projects by Program Area. Changes in the Number of Dairy Processing Plants and Changes in the Proportion of Total Sales Accounted for by Plants in Various Size Groups, Canada, 1961 and 1966. Costs per Dollar Value of Shipments of Goods of Butter and Cheese Plants by Size Groups of Plants, Canada. 1962. Production and Price of Milk According to Utilization. Quebec, 1956 to 1968. Milk Equivalent of Factory Products by Month, Quebec and Ontario, 1968. Creamery Butter Production per Region of Quebec, Monthly Index, 1966, June = 100. vi Page 29 34 34 38 39 41 43 51 56 58 60 62 63 LIST OF TABLES (continued) TABLE 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. All Census Farms, Census Farms Reporting Milking Cows and Census Farms Reporting Sales of Dairy Products, Number by County in Eastern Quebec, 1966. Census Commercial Farms, Commercial Farms Reporting Milking Cows and Sales of Dairy Products, and Commercial Farms Classified as Dairy Farms, Number by County in Eastern Quebec, 1966. Sales of Dairy Products Reported by All Farms and by Commercial Farms, and Proportion of Total Accounted for by Commercial Farms, by County in Eastern Quebec, 1966. Changes in The Number of Commercial and Non-Commercial Farms by County in Eastern Quebec, 1961 and 1966. All Census Farm Operators, Commercial and Non- Commercial Farm Operators Reporting Off-Farm Work by Groups of Days Worked off the Farm, Eastern Quebec, 1966. Number of Cows and Heifers, Two Years or Over, Milking or to be Milked, per Commercial Dairy Farm, by County of Eastern Quebec, 1966. Changes in Size of Dairy Farms, Quebec, 1956-1966. Percentage of Respondents with 10 Milking Cows or More Reporting Specified Types of Equipment in Eastern Quebec, July, 1969. Breeds of Dairy Cows Reported by Farmers with 10 Cows or More in Eastern Quebec, July, 1969. Proportion of A11 Farm Operators of a Given Age Group In Eastern Quebec, Quebec and Ontario, 1951 and 1966. Improved Agricultural Land Area Devoted to Major Crops, by County of Eastern Quebec, 1966. Hourly wages in Butter and Cheese Factories by Groups Based on Value of Sales, Canada, 1962. Per Capita Consumption of Dairy Products in Canada, Retain Weight, 1951-1953 and 1961-1963. Respondents' Intentions Concerning their Dairy Farming Enterprises. Respondents Favoring a Specific Strategy for Increasing Size of Herds, Number and Percentage. vii Page 65 66 67 68 69 71 71 76 79 82 84 94 112 136 138 LIST OF TABLES (continued) TABLE Page 30. Respondents Favoring a Specific Combination of Strategies for Increasing Yields of Dairy Herds, Number and Percentage. 138 31. Number of Heifers that Some Local Dairymen Might Buy per Year from the Dairy Stock Raisers at Various Prices. 140 32. Respondents Holding Specified Opinions Concerning Artificial Insemination, Number and Percentage. 140 33. Respondents in Three Dairy Herd Size Categories who are Likely to either Expand or not Expand Herd Size in the Next Five Years, Number and Percentage. 144 34. Respondents in Three Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production per Cow Likely to either Expand or not Expand Herd Size, Number and Percentage. 144 35. Respondents in Three Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production per Cow Reporting a Specified Herd Size, Number and Percentage. 146 36. Respondents in Two Dairy Herd Size Categories who Tend to Favor Specified Practices, Number and Percentage. 146 37. Respondents in Two Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production per Cow who Tend to Favor Specified Practices, Number and Percentage. 147 38. Distribution of Herd Sizes on 68 Farms, Eastern Quebec, 1969. 174 39. Composition of Herds with Respect to Age and Milk Production per Cow on 43 Small Herds and 25 Large Herds, Eastern Quebec, 1969. 175 40. Factors for Conversion of Records of Milk Production to the Mature-Equivalent Basis for Mixed-Bred Herds in Eastern Quebec. 177 41. Specifications for Four Dairy Rations Considered in this Study. 179 42. Expected Production Capacity of Heifers Raised from Respondents' Own Herds for Farm Groups I and II, Eastern Quebec. 184 43. Estimated Percentage of Cows Removed from the Respondents' Herds for Various Reasons, 68 Respondents, Eastern Quebec. 190 viii LIST OF TABLES (continued) TABLE 44. 45. 46. 47. 48. 49. 50. 51. 52. 53. 54. 55. Summary of Simulated Experiments Projected Outcomes for Farms I and II under Trend Conditions (Experiments 1 and 7). Projected Outcomes for Farm I under Alternative Program Strategies, 1969 and 1975. Projected Outcomes for Farm II under Alternative Program Strategies, 1969 and 1975. Ranking of Simulated Experiments on Basis of Present Value of Cash Flows Discounted at 6 per cent. Projected Net Change in Farm Capital Invested in Cows for Various Simulated Experiments. Levels of Milk Production Associated with Various Feeding Rates, Simulated and Measured in Survey. Projected Outcomes for Farm II with Increased Costs of Feed. Projected Outcomes for Farms I and II with Price of Purchased Replacements Set at $200 per Head. Projected Outcomes for Farm II Associated with a Higher Quality Range of Purchased Replacements. Estimated Variability in Returns and in Average Production per Cow for Farm II under Three Experimental Conditions. Projected Milk Production of Farms I and II. APPENDIX TABLES 1. Daily Production per Cow in Quebec, Ontario, and by County of Eastern Quebec, July lrst, 1966. Annual Forage and Grains Fed, and Milk Production per Cow: Dairy Herds of Mixed Breeds, Eastern Quebec, 1960. Values Assigned to Variables in Simulated Experiments. Projected Outcomes for Farm I Under Alternative Program Strategies. Projected Outcomes for Farm II Under Alternative Program Strategies. ix Page 193 198 201 205 209 211 213 221 223 224 227 236 257 263 265 271 272 LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE 1. Map Showing the Eastern Quebec Region. 2. Map Showing the Agricultural Zones in the Eastern Quebec Region. 3. Hypothetical Marginal Cost Curves for Two Different Technologies of Butter Production. 4. Hypothetical Market Equilibrium Situation when the Board Acts as a Buyer if Butter. 5. Hypothetical Market Equilibrium Situation when the Board Acts as Seller of Butter 6. System Relationships. 7. Generalized Flow Chart for Simulation MDdel. Page 26 31 99 108 109 157 163 LIST OF APPENDICES APPENDIX Page A. Methodological Considerations on Survey Design. 254 B. Factors Affecting Yields of Dairy Cows. 256 C. Questionnaire. 258 D. Summary of Survey Results on Feeding Rates. 263 E. Summary of Data Used in Various Simulated Runs. 265 F. Summary of Projected Outcomes for Farms I and II. 271 xi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION general -..__Pr0b3 smiltsaatian During the last fifteen years both the Federal Government of Canada and most provincial governments have shown greatly increased concern over serious disparities of income between regions as well as between areas within regions. This concern has resulted in greater public involvement in regional development programs. The most recent major legislation dealing Jith the problem of rural poverty in Canada is the Agricultural Rehabilitation and Development Act (ARDA) passed in 1962-1 Essentially, the ARDA is an arrangement for federal provincial costwsharing of approved projects for the development of depressed rural areas. These projects are activated by provincial project proposals and sanctioned by enabling agreements on the part of participating provinces. This thesis is concerned with one such project proposed for Eastern Quebec, an economically depressed area in the province of Quebec.2 As a result of this project a multi-sector planning study was undertaken in 1Past and current Canadian policies addressed to the problem of rural poverty in Canada are reviewed by Hadley Van Vliet. ”Canadian Approaches to Rural Poverty," Journal of Fagmugggngmics. vol 49 no 5. December, 1967, pp. 1209*24. See also Helen Buckley and Eva Tihanyi, Canadian Policies for_Rural Adjustment: A Stugy_9f the Economig_lmp§gt of ARDA, PFRAL and MMRA (Queen's Printer. Ottawa, Canada), Special Study No. 7, prepared for the Economic Council of Canada. October, 1967. 2Other projects financed by ARDA are concisely described by L E Poetsche. "Regional Planning for Depressed Rural Areas--The Canadian Experience." Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. XVI, no. 1, February. 1968 pp. 8-20, 2 1963 and completed in 1966 at a cost of $3.8 millions.3 The completed regibnal development plan included a series of recommendations for specific government action to induce improvements in the performance of existing industries and to facilitate the emergence of new economic activities in the secondary and service sectors. Agriculture, fish- eries, forestry, mining and tourism presently constitute the backbone of this regional economy (Table 1). The most serious criticism which was addressed to this regional project emphasized that no feasibility studies had been made for the individual projects recommended in the plan.4 This weakness was reco- gnized by public authorities who are now responsible for financing its implementation. Specifically, in the 1968 public document describing the nature of the inter-governmental agreement covering the implemen- tation of the Eastern Quebec plan, there is a clear expression of the need for further research on the programs recommended. The mandate reads as follows: The impact of the implementation of each program or group of programs (proposed in the Eastern Quebec Plan) has to be measured and assessed, and if necessary these programs have to be modified in order to achieve better results.5 This dissertation follows this mandate, assessing a number of the proposed programs for the first planning period (1968-75). This research :3A11 monetary data included in this study are expressed in Canadian currencies. They can be readily expressed in United States currencies by using the following ratio: $1 (USA)= $1.08 (Canada). 4Hadley Van Vliet, op. cit., p. 1216. R. Capel, "Development Plan for the Pilot Region: Lower St.Lawrence, Gaspe and Iles-de-la-Madeleine," Book review published in Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. XVI, no. 1, 1968, pp. 98-100. 5Department of Forestry and Rural Development, Lower St.Lawrence, Gaspe- and Iles-de-la-Madeleine Area of Quebec: Federal-Provincial Rural Development Agreement (Queen's Printer, Ottawa, Canada), 1968, p. 56. TABLE 1. The Importance of Economic Sectors in Eastern Quebec Based on Employment, 1963. m W Persons Employed by Sector Sector Numbera Proportion ('000 persons) (per cent) Primary 22.0 30.5 Agricultureb 13.0 18.0 Forestry, fisheries and mining 9 0 12.5 Secondary 13.2 18.3 Food and beverages 1.8 2.5 Pulp and paper 0.6 0.8 Lumber, construction and others 10.8 15.0 Tertiary 37.0 51.2 TOTAL 72.2 100.0 Source: Development Plan for the Pilot Region; Lower St. Lawrence, Gaspe and_;1es-de-la-Madeleine, A Summary, by Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Québec, and Rural Development Branch, Department of Forestry and Rural Development, Otana, June 1967. 8The estimates for agriculture are especially tentative because farming relies very heavily upon members of the farm operator's family as a source of labor in Eastern Quebec. A more relevant measure of the relative importance of specific sectors of economic activity in the regional economy would be the proportion of total income generated in each sector. Unfortunately, reliable data on only a few sectors of eco- nomiq activity are available. bSome sectors of economic activity hire workers for only a few months in a year. As a matter of fact, the number of persons employed in all sectors, with the possible exception of some activities in the service sector, fluctuates heavily over the year in the region. Since primary activities are more seasonal than others in the region, it must be emphasized that this table probably overestimates the importance of primary activities. These data are thus very crude indicators of the relative importance of specific sectors of economic activity in the region. 4 studies only the group of programs advocated for increasing the produc- tivity and profitability of dairy farming enterprises in the region. Some alternative dairy development strategies are also evaluated. Importance Dairy farming is presently an important source of income for a large portion of the rural population in Eastern Quebec. Sales of dairy products accounted for about 50 per cent of gross farm income in the re- gion in 1966. Evidence indicates;however that a large majority of the people involved in dairy farming in the area barely earn a subsistence income despite the fact that dairying is heavily subsidized. The planners' stated objective for the dairy farming industry is to increase productive efficiency. In order to achieve this objective they propose two general groups of programs. The first group of programs aims at creating exit opportunities for the people who want to discon- tinue farming. The second group of programs aims at increasing supply of adequate resources for the people who wish to further commit them- selves to dairy farming. The planners believe that both groups of pro- grams must be pursued simultaneously because of the limited prospects of a larger market for regional milk production. The planners'6 objective for the regional dairy farming industry is one over which reasonable individuals may disagree. This disser- tation intends to present evidence as to whether or not the policies 6Henceforth we shall use the term "planners" to mean the group of researchers who participated in the planning effort conducted in Eastern Quebec from 196? to 1966. the term "plan" to mean the policy recommen- dations that they advocated and the term "region" to specifically refer to Eastern Quebec. 5 proposed are likely to achieve increased productive efficiency rather than to directly Challenge the objective itself. What is not known yet is the following: Do the benefits to be generated by the proposed dairy develop- ment strategies in the area justify the costs of these actions? If not, are there alternative strategies that can be justified on that basis? These questions cannot be appropriately answered without sound empirical evidence on the expected impact.of various projects on farm income. Planners have not yet fully explored the likely impact of their policy recommendations within benefit-cost or other appropriate analy- tical framework. The reasons which might explain this situation are not altogether clear. There is some evidence indicating that the ARDA authori- ties failed to supply the planners with guidelines for project appraisal.7 Benefit-cost accounting was made a requirement for approval of projects by ARDA only after the development plan for Eastern Quebec had been completed. The thrust of this thesis is to show that reasonable estimates of the likely impact of alternative dairy development strategies on dairy farmers' income can be obtained. These estimates are essential to provide basic data for an economic appraisal of the various projects. Objectives The specific objectives of the study are the following: 1) to review the general regional problem situation and set forth the nature of the regional planning effort undertaken; 2) to determine the most important difficulties currently faced by the regional dairy industry; 7Hadley Van Vliet, op. cit., p. 1216 6 in the regional plan for solving the problems of the dairy farming industry; 4) to present evidence on regional dairymen's expressed prefer- ences regarding the pelicy alternatives considered in this study. These policy alternatives include (a) the establishment of special- ized dairy replacement stock farms, (b) improved feeding practices, and (c) farm consolidation and community pasture programs. Oiher alflérnanives considered are (d) subsidizing replacement purchases and (e) artificial insemination. 5) to determine which set of policy atternatives might most contribute to increasing the income of representative dairy farming enter- prises; 6) to indicate how the findings generated in this study might be used to develop an extensive benefit-cost analysis of alter- native dairy development programs. Methodology and Source of Information The model used in the analysis is based on a simulation technique developed by Robert F. Hutton.8 It is a general purpose model designed tosimulate the performance of a synthesized dairy enterprise under expe- rimental conditions. The model is particularly useful for projecting changes in profitability and productivity of a dairy enterprise associated with va- riations in herd size, feeding rations,rep1acement practices, cost of feed and price of milk. .A detailed description of the structure of the model 8Robert F. Hutton, A Simulation Technique for Making Management Decisions in Dairy FarmingzNarrative, Flow Chart and Computer Code Descrip- tion, Agricultural Economics Report No. 87, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, February, 1966. will be presented later in the study. This study focuses on a limited number of alternative dairy develop- ment strategies for improving the performance of the regional dairy farming industry. The model is used to simulate two synthesized dairy farms under the conditions which might prevail in the rggion under the various policy alternatives considered. In this study two main criteria are used to evaluate the likely consequences of the regional dairy development stra- tegies at the farm level. They are the net cash income per year of the dairy enterprise and the average production per cow per year. The model is used to project these performance criteria under alternative dairy herd improvement and/or feeding practices. The measured contributions of res- pective dairy development programs to the increases innnetccaSh income‘from dairying and in average yearly milk production per cow is then presented as a guideline for comparing the policy alternatives considered. 3 Mbst of the information used in this study comes from two sources. The first consists of the regional planning documents dealing with the agricultural sector and their supporting studies.9 The second source consists of primary data obtained from a sample survey which was undertaken 9Development Plan for the Pilot Region: Lower St.Lawrence,;Gaspe and Iles-de-la-Madeleine, A Summary, by Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Quebec, and Rural Development Branch, Department of Forestry and Rural Development, Ottawa, June, 1967. Esquisse du Plan: 1'Agricu1ture, published and edited by the Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Quebec, 1967. Plan de Dgygloppement. Région Pilote: Bas St-Laurenty,Gaspgsie et Iles-de-la-Madeleine, Chapitre II, "Objectif de Modernisation des Sec- teurs de Base Traditionnels, Deuxiéme Partie: Le Secteur de 1'Agricu1ture," Cahier' 3, published and edited by the Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Quebec, June, 1966. 8 for this research project.10 Many othersources of information are also drawn en in documenting the current problem situation faced by the regional dairy industry.11 10Henceforth, the survey will be referred to as Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. 11Numerous quoted from French documents are presented in this study. Theirtranslation is mine. PART 1 Regional Planning in Canada: The Case of Easterngguebec CHAPTER II EMERGENCE OF ECONOMIC PLANNING IN CANADA Government policies to offset regional agricultural disadvantages span the history of Canada. Federal policies directedtboaptieeuand income support, crop-failure assistance, and many other agricultural policies formed part of the measures used for promoting agricultural development through the post-Confederation period (from 1867 on). Combining with various provincial programs more or less oriented towards agriculture, they provided a broad overlay of rural welfare measures which eventually became major components of the current general agri- cultural policy in Canada. Those measures have apparently failed to eradicate the generalized hard-core poverty problem that still subsists in many rural areas in Canada. In the early 1960's legislators were prone to believe that eco- nomic planning within a regional framework might succeed where general policies had failed. This belief was instrumental in leading to the Eastern Quebec pilot planning study, the first major attempt on the part of the Canadian Federal Government to search for special solutions to the economic and social problems of a severely depressed area. 10 The Meaning of Development Plannigg The regional development plan for Eastern Quebec can first be examined by observing the underlying concepts conveyed by economic planning and by describing the conditions that surrounded its emergence in Canada. The many definitions of development planning stem from the very fact that both development and planning mean different things to dif- ferent people. For instance, if one were to agree with Myrdal's conten- tion that "the movement of the whole social system upwards is what all of us in fact mean by development,"1 and define planning as the "coor- dination of policies in order to attain and speed up development,"2 he could then argue that almost every country of the world is presently planning the path of her development. If, on the other hand, one were to adopt a more pragmatic point of view, he might agree with Stolper's proposition that "the actual planning problem consists of mobilizing and allocating resources for growth in the best manner that time and circumstances permit."3 For the purposes of this study, development planning means syste- matic and coordinated research undertaken either for or by public decision- makers in order to find a set of strategies that are likely to contribute the most to whatever economic and social objectives a country is striving I 1Gunnar Myrdal, Asian Drama: An Enquiry into the Poverty of Nations (New York: Pantheon, 1968), vol. 111, p. 1869. 21bid., p. 1864 3Wolfgang F. Stolper, Eganning Without Factsnyessons in Resource Allocation frgm Nigeria's Development (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1967), p. 52. 11 for. The set of strategies may include both private and public invest- mentnprojects, changes in public regulations, creation of new institu- tions and/or changes in the functions of on-going institutions, and much more. The way in which the research.im.conducted may or may not involve those people on whose initiative the implementation of a plan is likely to rest. The expression "likely to contribute" was purposedly introduce in the definition to point out that--in Lewis's words--"a plan is essentially a set of guesses about the future, since the assignment of priorities requires uncertain estimates of likely results, benefits and costs."4 On the Role of Planning The role of planning cannot be discussed in the abstract. In market economies, the role of planning for higher productivity in the private sector lies in finding a set of strategies which will most likely induce private persons to employ their time and resources more productively, given that the set of strategies is consistent with (l) the objectives of the society, (2) the quantity of resources and the amount of time available to implement these strategies, and (3) the specific interest of that part of the society which will most directly be affected by the set of strategies. There is no standard list of the ways and means whereby a govern- ment can contribute to raising the rate of growth in the private sector 4W. Arthur Lewis, Development Planning, The Essentials of Economic Policy? (New York: Harper and Row, l966),p. 25. "a...“ 12 of an economy. In this study, the role of planning is defined to include a combination to the following elements: 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) Exploring and assessing alternative objectives set out by public decision-makers and others in order to find out which of these objectives are consistent and can be achieved by the appropriately defined aggregate unit of a nation; Developing alternative sets of strategies which are consistent with the chosen objectives and which are most likely to induce the desired growth in the private and public sectors of the economy; Seeking information and analytical methods which are approp- riate for evaluating the relative merit of alternative sets of strategies; Setting forth specific projects and programs to carry out chosen sets of strategies; Presenting decision-makers and the public with sound estimates of the total economic and social impact for each alternative set of strategies; and finally, Estimating the commitments of public and private funds that each alternative set of strategies entails.5 These elements, viewed singularly or in combinations, are most commonly used in defining the role of economic planning in market eco- nomies. Whether or not more is expected from economic planning (such as rationing a commodity during a war period) seems to depend upon (1) the 5More specific elements which fit into these categories can be found in W. Arthur Lewis, op. cit., p. 22. 13 system of values held by a society, (2) the relative size of the public sector as compared to the private sector, (3) the nature and the degree of suddenness of problematic situations, (4) the status of the planning group in regard to other gobernment agencies and (5) the means of government intervention which are constitutionally recognized at a point in time. Planning in Canada Planning in Canada is in its early infancy. In the 1950's the need for greater coordination of public policies affecting the growth of the Canadian economy began to be expressed in both the political and the academic circles.6 Many people felt that one of the major problems that the Federal Government and the provincial governments would have .to focus upon in the 1960' was that of significant income disparities between provinces and between areas within provinces. It was also felt that the general front of Canadian welfare policy originating in the late 1940's had contributed little more than temporary alleviation to 6The need for coordination of Canadian agricultural policies has recently been stressed by McCalla, in whose opinion "A conglomeration of quasi-independent policies, without a broader set of coordinated objectives makes the adjustment of Canadian agriculture to changing market situations particularly difficult." See Alex F. McCalla, "A Review and Appraisal of Agricultural Policies in Canada," published in Agricultural Policy (Proceedings), Thirteenth Annual WOrkshop, Canadian Agricultural Economics Society, June 19-21, 1968, University of Guelph. 14 a self-perpetuating problem and that the costs of solving social prob- lems through welfare measures had been increasing too rapidly.7 The changes in public policy orientation were slow to come.8 It appears however, from the few changes that took place in the early 1960's, that most levels of government in Canada are committing themselves to a modest attempt to sobfie the problems of income disparities on an area basis. This approach is apparently based on the value judgment that the various regions of the country should be expected to share in the growth in total output and income of the nation as a whole. It is also based on the belief that it might be easier to achieve a coordination of economic policies on a local basis than at higher levels of decision-making. The surging commitment on the part of public decision-makers to search for solutions to the income disparity problem on an area basis gave rise to three main difficulties. On the one hand, the concept of economic regions--differing from political district boundaries--could not be readily defined in unequivocal terms. On the other hand a choice had to be made between the objective of maximizing the rate of growth of output and productivity for the benefit of a region without regard for the impact of its development on that of other regions and that of securing an appropriate balance in economic development among the various regions which, at the same time, would be consistent with 7H. Van Vliet argues that the Canadian concept of welfare policy reflects "the broader concepts of social welfare stimulated by European precedents, especially U.K. implementation of the cradle-to-the-grave philosophy of social security." See H. Van Vliet, op. cit., p. 1210. 8Van Vliet, op. cit., p. 1224, argues that "The commitment to the effort, in terms of both resources and concern, suggest that the war on poverty has scarcely been joined in Canada." - 15 the economic and social objectives of the country as a whole. The assumption underlying this discussion is that the growth rate of income recorded at the-n'a‘tiionall level is itself related to the nature of the interregional distribution. The exact nature of this relationship is a subject of controversy in Canada. The differences in viewpoint among economists and policy decision-makers appears to hinge heavily upon their appraisal of the degree of effectiveness in the organization and functioning of market forces. Not enough evidence is yet available to clearly determine whether or not the serious interregional disparities of income in Canada are significantly related to imperfections in operating market forces.9 The third major difficulty has to do with the present conflict of jurisdiction! between levels of government in Canada. This last issue is briefly elaborated in the following paragraphs. According to W.M; Nicholls, "Research in the national interest is a responsibility of the federal government" in Canada.10 However, any casual observer of the policital evolution of Canada over the last decade might admit that not everybody agrees over what does or should 9Further research on this issue is needed. Someipcoplefhéfiawe that operating market forces have not been so effective as to produce a significant convergence in the degree of interregional income differ- ences in Canada. Factual evidence confirming this belief is, however, at most cursory. See S.E. Chernick, Interregional Disparities in In- come (Queen's Printer, Ottawa, Canada), Staff Study No. 14, prepared for the Economic Council of Canada, August, 1966, p. 66. 10William M. Nicholls, Views on Rural Development in Canada (Queen's Printer, Ottawa, Canada), Special Study No. 1, prepared for the Canadian Council on Rural Development, 1967, p. 125. l6 constitute the national interest. The very challenge of the concept of national interest in Canada has been detrimental to the status of planning at all levels of government. The recent explosion of advisory groups (most of which are called Councils) serving specific levels of government“ reflects a need for coordination of economic and social policies in Canada. The regional development programs which have already been under- taken in Canada cannot be fitted within a national or even a provincial planning framework. The question whether Canada needs a more formal economic planning structure is beyond the scope of this research. Lat it be sufficient to point out that the issue of rural poverty in Canada has been instrumental in giving rise to regional development programs. The Need for UsingiProject Appraisal Criteria in Canada The question whether income redistribution to the benefit of a region such as Eastern Quebec should constitute an important objective in Canada cannot be answered by any scientific method. This is because the answer involves a series of value judgments with moral and ethical ramifications. However, the recognition of an important social objective as a policy goal must not preclude the simultaneous recognition of the economic costs and benefits. For instance, any government agency aware that a given set of strategies might contribute more than another set of programs to increase the well-being of dairy farmers in Eastern Quebec, 17 for a given cost, could be rightfully blamed if it proceeded to choose the latter set of strategies. The importance of sound economics has been frequently emphasized in public statements by leading representatives of various government agencies in Canada. Yet evidence indicatestthattfihe~valuable tool of benefit-cost accounting has played a veryylimited role in government investments until quite recently. This evidence was presented by various authors whose conclusions sustain the following comments by Buckley and Tihanyi: ARDA at least made some beginning in working out the methods of more rigorously applied benefit-cost principles.......Yet, in every day ARDA operations, statements of benefits in the most rudimentary terms are apparently acceptable as a basis for evaluating the merits of project sponsored from ARDA funds. There are several reasons for believing that benefit-cost account- ing studies are necessary for sound economic planning and that such studied need to be conducted at the policy formulation stage. The first general reason is that the benefit-cost analysis framework forces the planners to think in terms of alternative projects competing for scarce resources and to take a hard look at the possible outcomes of alternative strategies. The second general reason is that screening projects at the implementation stage may be too late in those cases where the research planning effort has created a momentun for new expec- tations regarding government policies. Much public controversy may be avoided by screening projects at the policy formulation stage itself. _ 11Helen Buckley and Eva Tihanyi, o . cit., p. 21 18 Methods for Valuing Alternative Development Projects Two methods of benefit-cost analysis are commonly used to appraise (dearelopment projects. The first method which is often referred to as fiJnancial analysts examines the private profitability of a given project. Arunual benefits, estimated on the basis of monetary revenues and costs acuzruing to the private entrepreneurs, are related to the amount of capital invested. The second method, usually called economic benefit- cnast analysis, has been defined in the following terms: Cost-benefit analysis is a practical way of assessing the desir- ability of projects, where it is important to take a long view (in the sense of looking at repercussions in the further, as well as the nearer, future) and a wide view (in the sense of allowing for side-effetts of many kinds on many persons, indus- tries, and regions, etc.) i.e., it implies the enumeration and evaluation of all relevant costs and benefits.12 There are three major conceptual differences between the private Prwxfitability criterion of financial analysis and the real profitability curiterion of economic cost-benefit analysis. These differences are the f011owing: 1. Economic analysis recognizes that the contribution of a project or a group of projects to the growth of the economy is a indirect as well as direct. The direct effects consist of the immediate contributions to production. The indirect effects are those generated by the project or group of pro- jects in all other sectors linked to the project. 12H.R. Prest, and R. Turvey, "Cost-Benefit Analysis: A Survey," The Economic Journal, vol. LXXV, no. 300, December, 1965, p. 683. l9 2. Economic analysis is not conceptually restricted to the use of actual prices as measures of economic value. Prices adjusted to reflect true opportunity costs to the economy are used when one, two or all three following circumstances prevail: a) some resources of the economy are not fully utilized; b) production under decreasing cost functions--which can be attributed to indivisibilities either in input or output industries-~characterized one or some of the sectors affected by the project; and/or c) market imperfections of different kinds exit in the economy. 3. Economic analysis relates benefits not exclusively to the private capital invested but rather to the sum total of annual costs which include both capital and project operation costs over time. Financial Analysis as a Step in Benefit-Cost Accounting Since private entrepreneurs normally respond to the monetary Ireturns accruing to them rather than to the economic returns--measured 21n.terms of opportunity costs-accruing to the total economy, it must 1>e emphasized that the economic benefit-cost analysis is not a substitute for financial analysis when the use of shadow prices is justified.13 g 13This argument may be clarified by an example. Suppose that a dairy development project proposed in Eastern Quebec was shown to have an economic benefit-cost ratio significantly higher than one but that hired labor was appropriately valued at zero cost. The important question is the following: Does the benefit-cost ratio imply that the dairy farmers will get enough benefits from the project to make a positive 20 The logic of this argument suggests that planners must be concerned with both the financial and the economic criteria for project appraisal if there are valid reasons to believe that the use of shadow prices is needed for computing the economic criterion. The analytical part of this study is restricted to estimating the relative merit of alternative development strategies for increasing the well-being of dairy farmers in the regional economy of Eastern Quebec. The financial analysis criterion is therefore used. There are valid reasons to believe, however, that the current market price for some important factors of production might differ from their real oppor- tunity costs in alternative uses in the regional agriculture. Evidence on these possible differences is presented in the following chapters. Agpicultural Planning in a Canadian Perspective Planning is a concerted and coordinated development effort. Whether or not planning for agricultural development can be viewed as a major subset of general planning depends upon the relative importance of agriculture in the total problem situation. It might also depend in practice. upon (1) the way in which the public institutions servicing agriculture (including the Ministry of Agriculture) define their con- stituency and (2) the willingness of these institutions to participate into a concerted effort at either the national or the regional level. response to it? The answer is "not necessarily" because the dairy farmers are preoccupied not by the real value of the hired worker in alternative use but rather by the wage rate that they must pay in order to hire labor services. Rationality on the part of the dairy farmer must there- fore be measured in terms of his financial costs and returns. 21 The early regional development efforts undertaken in Canada were directed primarily to land-use conversion and resource-oriented forms of agricultural development. There was a tendency on the part of the researchers who participated in these studies to pay little attention to the growing interdependence between agriculture and the nonfarm sectors and to disregard the relative importance of nonfarming activities in rural areas. However, a significant shift in emphasis began to take place in the early 1960‘s partly as a result of a revision in the ARDA legislation. It was thought that government funds allocated to planning research would probably provide a substantially more significant impact on disadvantaged rural areas if research were carried more strongly to encompass structural readjustments of agriculture and the broader development of nonagricultural phases of rural economy. Agricultural economists were particularly affected by this change in program focus. Those who participated in the early efforts mostly as farm management specialists are now required not only to contribute to an understanding of resource adjustments at the farm level but also to suggest means for strengthening the interdependence between agricul- tural and nonagricultural sectors in depressed rural areas. The essential newness and as yet limited extension of the above emphasis precludes definitive assessment of the future importance of agricultural planning in Canada. However, there are some reasons for believing (1) that there will probably be a substantial increase in the demand for agricultural planners in Canada, and (2) that agricultural economists will be asked to perform as members of planning teams concerned with a broad array of problems, including the potential contribution of. 22 the agricultural industry to the future development of depressed rural areas. The regional approach to development planning that has begun to emerge in Canada during the last decade can be theoretically connected with what V. Ruttan has called "the industrial impact hypothesis."14 The industrial impact hypothesis postulates that economic development tends to occur more rapidly in specific locational matrices which are primarily industrial-urban in composition and that certain agricultural areas of a country appear to benefit more from their favorable location in relation to such centers than other agricultural areas located at the periphery of these centers. Discussing the theoretical as well as the practical implications of this hypothesis for regional planning in Canada is beyond the scope of this study. It must be emfliasized how- ever that an agricultural planning approach relying heavily upon that hypothesis might lead to disregarding an important factor, namely the ability of a region to export agricultural commodities for which it has comparative advantage. It is notan overstatement to suggest that agricultural economists with sound expertise in agricultural market 14Vernon Ruttan, "Growth Stage Theories and Agricultural Develop- ment Policy," The Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol.IX, no. 1, 1965, p. 23. This general hypothesis has many proponents. In North America its major proponent has been T.W. Schultz who expressed it in the form of three tentative statements concerning the ways in ‘which economic development appears to propagate itself over a country's geographical space. See T.W. Schultz, The Economic Organization of Agriculture (New York, Toronto, London, McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc.), 1953, p. 147. Other proponents' views are summarized in Bela Balassa, The Theory of Economic Integration (Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1961), pp. 193-98. 23 analysis might have much to contribute to regional planning in Canada. Their absence might otherwise lead to a serious aggravation of the agricultural surplus problems that have plagued Canadian agriculture for the last decade. Economic planning is essentially a team effort. The nature of the regional income disparity problems currently existing in Canada indicates that the demand for agricultural economists with some exper- tise in planning might substantially increase in this country in the foreseeable future. The nature of the planning approach which has been brought to bear on these problems in turn indicates that agricultural economists will be expected to work in close<:ooperation with.specialists in other disciplines. Summary The inroads so far made into the complex problem of rural poverty in Canada represent a bare beginning. Canada has just begun an approach to the problem of income distribution within its lagging rural areas aftermany years of concentration on the income distribution problem between agriculture and other sectors of the economy. The program activities undertaken so far reflect a serious lack of a basic theory of area and regional economy as viewed within the national perspective. Their effectiveness has been partly dissipated by failure to approp— riately evaluate the payoff accruing to alternative uses of public funds for alleviating rural poverty. This points out the need for concerted and coordinated efforts where stringent project appraisal criteria are applied for screening 24 alternative development strategies. The relative importance of agri- culture in the poverty areas of Canada suggests that the expertise of agricultural economists might be in greater demand in the foreseeable future. Their expected contributions may need to shift somewhat from farm management research to macro supply and demand analysis. However, the expertise of farm management specialists will continue to be needed for finding effective ways and means of implementing agricultural devel- opment strategies, particularly with regard to the incentives which farmers need in order to change their farming methods and production patterns in desirable directions.15 15The ways in which farm management specialists might substantially contribute to planning for agricultural development are explored in detail in Rainer Schickele, Farm Managgment Research for Planning Agricultural Development (New York: Agricultural Development Council, ADC Reprint, December, 1966). CHAPTER III THE GENERAL PLANNING PROBLEMS AND OBJECTIVES IN EASTERN QUEBEC This chapter gives an overall view of the recent changes that were wrought into the social and economic organization of Eastern Quebec. Special emphasis is laid upon the economic situation of the agricultural sector. This information is presented as a background for understanding the general objectives that were set forth in the regional development plan. Definition of the Region To study the social and economic problems currently faced by the population of Eastern Quebec, let us first circumscribe the region and examine its recent economic and social evolution. The Eastern k Quebec region comprises the following nine counties: Riviére-du-Loup, Témiscouata, Rimouski, Matane, Matapédia, Bonaventure, Gaspe-North, Gaspe-South and Iles-de-la-Madeleine. The area, with the exception of Iles-de-la-Madeleine county, is bounded on the south by the province of New Brunswick and on the North by the St.Lawrence River (Figure l). Iles-de-la-Madeleine, located 120 miles away from the mainland eastern boundary of the territory, is recognized to share very little economic complementarity with the mainland area of Eastern Quebec. Moreover, this county has been treated as separate geographical entity in the 25 26 I T I I l I qt t-I-flm‘ 61100 O 49- L- River J ‘9 2.3-3: 4811 ' IfsQe—ln 11.61610 0 Scale in miles” 0 5 1—————1 ‘091 .f‘ .00' d U 0” \‘o. I .. Province of Quebec Figure 1. Map Showing the Bantu-‘1 Quebec iiu{_-,'C.'.~'.}Il. 27 development plan. Therefore, for the purposes of this study the Eastern Quebec region excludes Iles-de-la-Madeleine county. The Human Resources The population of Eastern Quebec increased at a decreasing rate from 1901 until about 1961, when it started to decrease in absolute terms (Table 2). An important exception to this trend occured between 1931 and 1941, when the population of the area increased by 23 per cent. Althoggh no precise estimates can be obtained, cursory evidence indi- cates that this exceptional diversion from the long-run trend can be partly attributed to the so-called "retour a la terre"(back-to-the-farm) movement which took place in Quebec during the depression period and its aftermath. An interesting study has shown that the characteristics of the farms located in the rural towns incorporated before 1931 dif- fered substantially from that of the farms established in towns incor- porated after 1931.1 The first farm settlers were apparently apt at selecting the most ecologically suitable soils while the wave of would- be farmers of the 1930's apparently had to settle on types of soils generally less suitable for agriculture. A peculiar characteristic of the region is the relatively high proportion of the population classified as rural non-farm. The rural farm population decreased by almost 50 perrrcan't between 1951 and 1966 1Yves Dubé and Jean-Marie Martin, Problemes de 1*Agriculture dans la Région du Bas Saint-Laurent (published and edited by the Département des Sciences Sociales de L'Université Laval, Quebec City, Canada), Le Conseil d'Orientation Economique du Bas Saint-Laurent, Quebec, 1963, pp. 81-106. 28 while the rural non-farm population did not start to decrease until around 1961 (Table 2). Part of this phenomenon can be attributed to the change of definition of a census farm between 1951 and 1961.2 However, adding up rural farm and rural non-farm population eliminated this conceptual inconsistency. The joint estimate indicates that the absolute importance of these two groups has been slowly eroded but their relative proportion of the total population was still 62.7 per cent in 1966. The Natural Resources The region is typically rural. The activities of the people in the area were almost exclusively centered on the use and transformation of natural resources until around 1900. They still.are, to ajvery significant extent. These resources have been described in the fol- lowing terms: An unexplored underground, marginal farm lands, a limited forest, a limited stock of cheap fish species and a touristic potential which, up to now, has not been put into advantages. The situation is aggravated by the fact that this real but marginal reservoir of natural resources does not support an adequate industrial sector. At the present time, there are only a few important industries in the territory, and out of five hundred and sixty- one industries, four hundred employ less than fifteen people each.3 For the purposes of this study attention is concentrated on the resources of the agricultural sector. Various technical studies which 2See footnote "a" of Table 2, for the definitions of urban, rural non-farm and rural farm population. 3Francois Poulin, "The Planning of Regional Development: Eastern Quebec," Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. XIV, no. 1, 1966, pp. 7-8. 29 .momomnnm mamaoo now muonunnnmoo an newness nofime mo omsmoon uaoumnmaoo non one Hman on nonnn muons .nOHansmon anew Hanan manna conuwnnmoa swan: manna conned unmon kuOu masses conuwasnom Enmmncon Hanan .mommo noon cH .nwom anon>onm can an onoe no omw mo muonoonm nonpuanonnww mo modem sunz nonow onos no oco mo wcnpaon nonpuanonnww no we mononnne mamaoo now vocnmoo ems anew m use womn>on mp3 a0nunnnmov mnnu .Homn nH .onoE no omum on manuaSOEm oan :n nonuonponn Hensuanonnwm nun3 onnm an monom oonnu on oco Eonm Anny no .onnm an onoE . monoo oonnu Anv vomnnmaoo nonnz one uno ponnnmo one econumnoao Hennuasonnmm non£3 no wcnoaos n so wnn>nH mnomnon flaw wnnmnnmaoo mm ponnmoo mp3 conumnnmon :Enmm: as» .Hmma :H ”Enmmucoa one Snob .uo: no woumnomnoocn noSuos3 .onoe no odmoon ooo.H mo momeHn> one mnzou .monuno an wcn>nH conumnnmon can mopnnocn mamnnmm .eoan on noan .semamo .msmuuo .monumnumum no smonsm concneon .woonmm .oz onwoawumo .Amonumnnouomnwso mannanm>w non.. .mpmcmu mo mnmnoo "monsom m.~ a a: «6.7 we «1» + H: w.m .. mg 003 non... HS m.mm.. mm 113+ 2: H.NH+ 3m 33 mm m2 H N1».— .. RN . .33 .<.z .<.z .<.z Emu... New Hiya .<.z .<.z .<.z «.mae. hma Hmmfi .<.z .<.z .<.z Twat oz :3 .<.z .<.z .<.z mtg... a3 :3 .<.z .<.z .<.z wHH HO¢H Auamu peso Aooo.v Angus “use Aooo.v Ausmu uoaVAooo.V Assoc suavaooo.v owdwso nonanz .mwmeno nonesz wwwmnu nonEnz owcmno nonaaz mo puma mo oumm no snow mo oumm new» nowadaamom Bnmmnaoz Henna nonumfisnom Enemnawnsm conuwanmom swan: conuwasmom Hmuom. w.oo¢~ Ou Hmaa .Enmmucoz Henna can Bnmmuamnam.cmnnb an GOHumHamom HenOHwom can no nonunnnnnmnn one .oomH on Homa .oonono anoumwm mo :OHumHnmom .N mumdfi 30 were made in the agricultural areas of the region appear to support the following generalizations. The region's cool climate and abundant water supply make it well-suited for growing grass. Grains and par- ticularly oats appear to grow equally well. Because of the abundance of weeds cereals are mostly grown as shelter and forage crops. Cereals grown for grain, however,_are mostly limited to coastal areas where the sea moderates the climate. The humidity which tends to favour growing of forage crops also poses a serious problem for their storage. The ecological conditions of the region make it difficult to dry hay in the field while maintaining good quality in storage. The climate of the region is alSo suited to produce a few vegetable and fruit crops, especially potatoes. The region can be meaningfully divided into five agricultural zones where the climate, the type of soils and the topography are unequally favorable to the development of a viable farming industry (Figure 2). The physical characteristics of these zones can be described as follows: 1. Zone A. Comprising less than 25 per cent of the settled area of the region, this zone is considered the most ecologically favourable to the development of the farming industry. It is suitable for growing cereals and for harvesting two crops of hay per year. Out of the 11,314 farms recorded in the region in 1961, 3,796 were located in this zone. 2. gppg_§. This zone has proportionately less cleared arable land than zone A. Its arable soils are also of inferior 31 .1033 3385 snowman one In noaoa Hannaddenfid on: minnonm an! .N 9:63 .3 .a :3 .Wm fine-ism A .01.??va 13.73133 can cause .oelonuaqlum .333 33mg“ veanm on» non :3 vac-E3925 «condom mu11 .0 .onn- an onuom . unnann anon 32 quality. The climate is more rigorous and cereal growing is 'more hazardous in zone B than in zone A. Some 3,193 farms were located in that zone in 1961. 3. Zone C. This zone has only 16 pervcent of the region's cleared arable land but its soils are particularly well- suited for agriculture. However, the climate is more rigorous than zone B. Cereals cannot be grown except as a nurse crop to be harvested as fodder and only one cut of hay per year is possible. Some 2,088 farms were recorded for this zone 1961. 4. Zone D. This is the most disadvantaged of the region's agri- cultural zones. Its cleared arable land is stony and poorly drained. The climate is unsuitable for cereals. Some 1,185 farms were located in this zone in 1961. 5. Zone E. Despite the fact that it is considered ecologically unsuitable for any agricultural crop, this zone had 1,052 farms in 1961. These farms were mostly subsistence and part- time farming operations.4 The technical difficulties associated with farming activities in Eastern Quebec appear to increase significantly as one goes from zone A to zone E. On the one hand, the rate of disappearance of farm opera- tions has recently been more rapid in zones C, D and E than in zones A and B (Table 3). On the other hand, commercial farms are now substantially 4Factual information on these physical characteristics of the region was drawn from "Development Plan for the Pilot Region: Lower St.Lawrence, Gaspé and Iles-de-la-Madeleine, A. Summary," op. cit., pp. 46-500 ‘JL 33 more numerous in zones A and B than in the other zones (Table 4).5 As a matter of fact, about one farm operation out of two was a commer- cial farm in zone A, one out of three in zone B, one out of four in zone C and only one out of six in zones D and E, in 1966. Major Resource Problems in Agriculture Eastern Quebec is considered as one of the most economically depressed areas of Canada. While the use of average measures has its limitations, some comparisons between the Province of Quebec as a whole and the region of Eastern Quebec might illustrate the nature and extent of the problem situation which was faced by the planners. For example: 1. Personnel disposable annual income per capita has been roughly estimated at $ 606 in Bonaventure, $ 643 in Gaspé (Gaspe-East and West), $ 647 in Matane and Matapédia, $ 693 in Riviére-du- Loup and Témiscouata and $ 800 in Rimouski, as compared a) $ 1217 for the Province as a whole in 1961. The comparable figure for the populous region of Mentreal was $ 1444 per capita in the same year.6 2. Transfer payments accounted for $ 58 million (or 27 per cent) of a total disposable income of approximately $ 220 million 5For census purposes, commercial farms are defined as agricultural holdings of one or more acres with a value of agricultural products, in the 12 months prior to the census, of $ 2,500 or more (excluding institutional farms). 6Gerard Vibien, Répartition Régionale du Revenu Personnel au Qpébec,ol96l, Plannificationcfi: Développement Regional, Serie II Rapport dUXnalyse, Cahier II/3, Published by the Conseil d'Orientation Economique du Quebec, Quebec, November, 1967, p. 122. in; 34 TABLE 3. Number of Farms Per Zone, and Rate of Disappearance of Farms, 1961 to 1966. m Zones Number of Farms 1966-1961 X 100 1961 1966 1961 (per cent) A 3,796 3,122 -l7.8 B 3,193 2,540 -20.5 C 2,088 1,530 -26.7 D and E 2,237 1,714 -23.4 Total 11,314 8,906 -21.3 Source: 1966 Census of Canada: Agriculture, Quebec, Catalogue No. 96-606, Dominion Bureau of Statistics, Ottawa, Canada, February, 1968. 3Farm operations were allocated by zones according to the list of muni- cipalities specified in "Plan de Développement," Cahier 3, op. cit. pp. 64-71. TABLE 4. Total Number of Farms and Number of Commercial Farms Per Zone, 1966. Zones Number of Farms 1966 Commercial X 100 Total Commercial Total (per cent) A 3,122 1,435 46.0 B 2,540 997 39.3 C 1,530 391 25.6 D and E ;,1;3 ,__g§§ 16.6 Total 8,906 3,108 34.9 ww— Source: Same as Table 3. aSame remark as in Table 3 35 recorded for Eastern Quebec in 1961.7 The comparable figure for the Province of Quebec as a whole was 13 per cent in 1961. It must also be pointed out that gdvernment financial aid granted to agriculture in the region represented about 40 per cent of gross income from sales of farm products.8 3. Approximately 38 per cent of the labour force was engaged in primary seasonal activities in Eastern Quebec in 1963, com- pared to 15 per cent for the Province as a whole. Mbreover, seasonal unemployment was considerable in the former area. It has been estimated that approximately 35 per cent of the wage earners in Eastern Quebec were unemployed for more than six months in 1963.9 Although more precise data are not available for comparing Eastern Quebec with other areas of Canada on a real income basis, these indicators describe a regional economy which is seriously depressed.10 A discussion of the major social problems associated with low incomes and high levels of unemployment in the region is beyond the scope of this study. 7Ibid., p. 119. 8Francois Poulin, op. cit., p. 8. 9Ibid., p. 7 10Even if one makes adjustments for spatial price differences, the income differences tend to remain large between regions of Canada. Evidence on this matter can be found in S. E. Chernick, op. cit., pp. 47-51. u~:.‘wa-'rc-'pr - 36 The main issue which is further explored in this study is the following: What is the combination of economic forces which has led to the general economic stagnation presently experienced in Eastern Quebec? A possible answer to this question is suggested in the following pages. Problems Related to Migration Patterns Perhaps the lack of natural resources alone does not suffice to explain why poverty is such a serious problem in Eastern Quebec. Low educational levels and disproportionafie presence of the least productive population age groups may be important causal factors. Consider. for example that: 5 1. Eastern Quebec attracted population from other areas of the Province of Quebec during the early land settlement period (1850-1900) and also during the depression and its aftermath (1930-1940). 2. The natural rate of increase (birth rate minus death rate) in the regional population was still as high as 15.5 per cent over the period 1951-1956 as compared to a 11.6 per cent for the province of Quebec as a whole over the same period.11 3. The level of education of the regional population was esti- mated to be consistently and substantially less than the provincial average.12 11Robert D. Hirsch, Gerard Vibien ahd Bernard Robert, L'Origine et la Nature desyDgsiquilibres Régionaux au Quebec, Planification du Develop- pement Regional, Sgrie II Rapport d'Analyse, Cahier ii/2, published by the Conseil d'Orientation Economique du Québec, Québec, February, 1968, p. 73. 121b1d., p. 109 37 4. The net regional outmigration totalled 35,334 people between 1951 and 1961. Most of the people who left the region from 1951 to 1961 were between 15 and 44 years of age.13 5. The regional cities and towns have grown very slowly. Indeed the regional population is presently distributed among 200 small localities located mostly along a 500-mile coast-line. The ten most important towns in the region have a total popu- lation of about 60,000 people or 20 per cent of the regional population. 6. Selectivity of migration has apparently contributed to leave a regional population which is seriously distorted in its age distribution characteristics as compared to the rest of province of Quebec (Table 5). It may logically be hypothesized, on the basis of these facts, that two long-run factors have been particularly defavorable to the economic development of the region since 1940. The first factor has to do with the increasing degree of selectivity in migration patterns. The second factor consists of the apparent failure of low wage rates to attract investments in the region. No one of these factors is unique to Eastern Quebec. The combination of these factors, however, appears to have been particularly effective in generating serious social and economic problems in the region since about 1940. 13Ibid., pp. 75 and 80. 38 TABLE 5. Percentage Distribution of Population by Twenty-Year Age Groups in Eastern Quebec and in all Other Areas of the Province of Quebec, 1966. Age Groups Proportion of Total Population in Specified Age Groops Eastern Quebec All Other Areas of Quebec (per cent) (per cent) 0-19 51.7 43.0 20-39 22.6 28.0 40-59 17.0 19.9 60 and over 8.7 9.1 100.0 100.0 Source: Compiled from 1966 Census of Canada (Ottawa, Dominion Bureau of Statistics), Catalogue No. 92-610, vol. I (1-10), Population, Age Groups, March, 1968. Nature and Resource Problems of Agriculture In the early 1960's, primary agricultural activities--that is activities which can be directly associated with farming--absorbed about 16 per cent of total regional labour force of about 83,000 people.14 In the meantime, census reports indicated that 65.6 per cent of the popu- lation in Eastern Quebec, as defined herein, was nonurban by residence (Table 2). The difference between these estimates indicates that a sub- stantial proportion of the regional population earns a living in rural activities that are not directly related to farming.15 14F. Poulin, op. cit., p. 1 15The number of people who live and work in the rural areas of the region. is probably smaller than the number of people classified as non- urban by residence. 39 The Importance of Dairying in the Region The production of dairy commodities is the predominant source of income from farming in the region. Milk sold on the market accounted for 46.7 per cent of total farming income derived from the sales of agricultural commodities in 1965 (Table 6). Moreover, the predominance of dairy salvage in terms of the regional beef output leads to the con- clusion that total regional marketings of cattle to yards and plants are in the form of heifers, calves and culled cows.16 In addition the proportion of total annual milk production which is fed to livestock skim milk may be quite significant in Eastern Quebec. However no precise estimate of the quantity of milk used as an input on own farms could be obtained. TABLE 6. Value of Agricultural Products Sold by Eastern Quebec Farmers, by Groups of Products, 1965. m w Groups of Products Value Percentage for Specified Groups ($'000) (per cent) Dairy products 10,131 46.7 Pigs 3,579 16.9 Cattle 3,196 14.7 Field crops 1,420 6.5 Forest produtts 1,283 5.9 Poultry Products 880 4 2 Others Cl,l91 5 5 All groups $ 21,688 100.0 Source: 1966 Census of Canada: Agriculture, Quebec, op. cit., Table 23,1 to 23.10. 16T.C. Kerr, An Economic Analysis of the Feed Freight AssiStance Policy, published by the Agricultural Economics Research Council of Canada, Ottawa, Canada, Publication No. 7, Spetember, 1966, pp. 103-05. 40 The general structure of regional farming includes the following features: 1. In terms of income generated through the sales of agricultural commodities, the dairy enterprise might, with very few restrictions, be currently considered the mainstay of farming in the region. 2. Dairy enterprises can be found on various types of farms. 17 The farms on which they are found have either one or a com- bination of the following enterprises; a) a b) a c) a d) a e) a f) a dairy enterprise; combination of dairy-related crops; swine enterprise; forestry-related enterprise;18 chicken enterprise; potato enterprise; and g) other minor enterprises. No data are available for determining how many farms have a given combination of these enterprises. However, census data tend to indicate that combinations a) and b) usually in con- junction with c) and/or f) are most frequently found. 17There were 7,468 farm operators (out of a total of 8,906 census farm operators) who reported cows potentially in lactation, in 1965. 18The forest occupies 14,000 of the 16,000 square miles of Eastern Quebec. A minor fraction of this forest area extends on the border of current farm areas. However forest-related enterprises appear to decrease in importance as a source of farm income in the region. 41 3. The few farms which do not have dairy enterprises tend to have smaller annual gross sales of agricultural products. Only one census farm out of four did not report any sales of dairy products in Eastern Quebec. in 1965. Moreover, 93.9 per cent --or 2,162 out of 2,302 census farms-- of those farms sold less than $2,500 of agricultural produCts in 1965 (Table 7). TABLE 7. All Census Farms and Census Farms not Reporting Sale of Dairy Products, Eastern Quebec, 1965. Class of Sales All Census Farms Census Farms Not Reporting Sales of Dairy Products (value of sales) (number) (number) $2,500 and more 3,108 140 50- 2499 24_7_8_2 2,163 TOTAL 8,890 2,302 Source: 1966 Census of Canada: Agriculture, Quebec, Catalogues No. 96- 636 and 96-606. Evidence on Low Returns to Factors of Production in Regional Agriculture The returns accruing to the factors of production committed to farming are low. Yet nobody has been able to accurately estimate regional net farm income.19 This is understandable since consistent data on farm costs are not yet systematically collected in the region. However, crude approximations made in this study indicate that very few farmers 19By net farm income we mean the residual income with which a farm operator is left to remunerate his own labor, his capital and managerial ability. 42 might earn their living from farming alone in Eastern Quebec (Table 8). Farms might be appropriately classified into the fol- lowing categories: 1. Farms with the largestygrowth potentials. This category might include those farms which reported sales of agricultural products of more than $ 10,000. Table 8 indicates that there were 174 such farms in Eastern Quebec in 1965. It is tenta- tively suggested that these farms might possess some combina- tions of the following characteristics: a) operator's superior managerial ability; b) favorable location vis-a-vis the regional urban markets; c) enough capital and borrowing capacity to finance the acquisition of additional resources; d) operator devoting most of his work time to the farming operation; e) relatively high productivity. Farms with restricted growthypotentials. This category might comprise those farms which reported sales of agricultural products of more than $ 5,000 and less than $ 10,000. Some 945 farms came under this category in 1965. The major barrier faced by these farm operators might be that of getting hold of additional funds to finance further growth. Furthermore, the probability that these farmers will continue farming in foreseeable future might be relatively high. Farms without current growth potentials. This category con- sists of those farms which reported between $ 2,500 and $5,000 43 .wump oumnnaonnnm mo xomn e on one mononuceumnsm on nonnmo nonuo some wanuwmaoaaoo one momenn omonu gonna ou ucouxo may .menmm oEoocn newnma mo no>mm an mans m mosoonunn on mecca manna Some ou :mnoenmm on wannnoom oEoonn no: nonuo: mo ooo.aw manned .odm: nosuo osu no .manmm oeoocn noHHmBm mo no>mm an wens m mopponunn on meson :oEooan non anew Hmonuonnodhnz enameoo On mommmao Ham now uaoo non on an conumonamnuase any .onmn oco can :00 .omsos oSu mo oaaw> Hanson one coon poEnmaoouoEon one noonponnnoaos mo onam> nozn .mmmao some now pom: :oEoodn mmonw some: «0 ucoo non om um woumEnummm .womH mash .momcmu .mBmuuo monumnumum no septum scapegoo .oos-ea .oz pawonssmu .opnmsa1.ppsunsonnw< "memeso no spasms soon "suppom oam.w aw~.n mso.n ooo.n me own mew -Om ome.~ nn~.n ooo.n AHN m~n aan.n -omm mno.~ mmm.n ooo.n mmm omw.n aaq.~ -oo~.n a¢~.n sma.n coo.n ems man.m sen.m -oom.~ can Nnm.~ coo.n Nam.n mam.s aaa.s -omn.m m~n mam.~ ooo.n mam.n om~.o as¢.n -ooo.m can m~s.m coo.n mwo.~ omn.m mma.m -oom.s NNH omn.s coo.n omn.m cow.un aaa.en-ooo.oH an coo.n coo.n coo.s ooo.o~ ama.s~-ooo.mn a ooo.on ooo.n coo.a ooo.om mam.sm-ooo.m~ o oom.nn coo.n oom.0n coo.mm once pas-ooo.mm Anonescv Ame Ame Ame Awe Awe Ansmv_ Ame Ame any mango comm oamuoe nanoEnmm OH wannnoom moEoonH Snub mmwwu.de1oomD oeoocH emmm. an menmm mo nonanz oEoocH uoz nosuo uoz Hmonuonuomhm :oeoonH amono: mmono mo mango .momH .oonono anoummm .oeoocH Bnmm uoz Hencc< mo mommmao an manmm mo nonanz .w wam¥a monnumnocH mnmEHnm can wannsnowwscmz .Amonumnumum mo awonsm connnEon .momnwo .manuov .monnuommasmz mo mnmcoo Hmnnd< .ooaH can Nomalsnonnouomm memo noonnom o.oo~ oaa o.o0n new m.m~- mom.n can.n nsuon «.mm 4mm. s.o~ .me s.sw. as «N pupa ens coo.m m.ns ens w.wm mum a.m~+ man man aaaaams. on coo.n m.nn enn n.en ans H.s 1 sun can a.¢a¢ on com ~.~n nun m.mn nmn m.~n- «cm was a.aae on cow ~.e Ne m.n no a.wm- sou mma a.aon as con m.n ma n.~ mu s.we- can Hum a.aa as on m.o m s.o m w.mm- no nan a.ae cu mu n.o n n.o n m.n¢- aw es a.sN on on o.o o o.o o o.om+ a s .oH pupa: eApapu ppaVAooo.ooo.wVAuapo uoavaooo.ooo.mv Assoc ppav Assesses Appeasav Aooo.wv conunononm onHm> nonunoaonm onnm> adono coma Hood nmo>,nom p s a n n o a n an «memes spasm no pans> mo spam no momma kuoa mo GOnunomonm one spasm mo osHm> connmnomd‘nn museum mo nonesz anono onnm % .oomH one Hana .mpmcmo .mnonw ounm some an madman no new mouanooo< moanm annoy mo cowunomonm on» an momnmso one mucunm wcnmmooonm hnnwn mo nonenz as» an mownmso .oH mamms 57 Assuming that butter and cheese plants have shared in this trend, it appears that economies of size may be one to the major variables accounting for this rapid structural evolution.5 As a matter of fact, aggregate data indicate that the larger the butter and cheese plants in Canada, the smaller their variable costs per dollar or sales (Table 11).6 A technical study of the Eastern Quebec butter industry shows that the regional plants have failed to keep up with the national trend. The largest butter plant in the region processed 33 million pounds of milk while the other reported less than 15 million pounds of milk in 1963. It has been estimated that, given the input and output prices in the region and the current level of technology available, a specialized butter plant must process between 50 and 60 million pounds of milk a year in order to produce at least costs, whereas a diversified 5Reporting of data on plants processing only butter and cheese has been discontinued in 1963. Apparently this modification in the reporting of data on Canadian dairy processing industries can be attributed to increase in product diversification within the industry. 6No data on fixed costs were available at the national level. Regional studies which have been made indicate, however, that admin- istration is one of the high cost items in butter manufacturing. In general administration expenses decline as the volume of butter increases. See Ferdinand Ouellet, La Consolidation des Usines Laitié- res dans la Région du Bas St-Laurent-Gaspésie, published and edited by Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Québec (BAEQ), 1964, and W.B. Rogers and H. S. Baker, "An Economic Analysis of the Alberta Butter Industry," Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. XVI, no. 1, February, 1968, pp. 40-44. 58 dairy processing plant must process between 100 and 150 million pounds of milk a year in order to make the most efficient use of its resources.7 TABLE 11. Costs per Dollar Value of Shipments of Goods of Butter and Cheeselflants by Size Group of Plants in Canada, 1962.a Costs per Dollar Absolute Difference Between of Sales Consecutive Size Groups $ 10,000 to 24,999 $029760“ 25,000 to 49,999 029465‘ -0.0295 50,000 to 99,999 0.9491 90.0026 100,000 to 199,999 0.9384 -0.0107 200,000 to 499,999 0.9374 -0.0010 500,000 to 999,999 0.9354 -0.0020 1,000,000 to 4,999,999 0.9326 -0.0118 5,000,000 and over 0.8855 -0.0381 TOTAL 0.9261 Source: Dairy Factories, 1962 (Ottawa, Canada, Dominion Bureau of Statistics), Industry Division, Catalogue No. 32-209, June, 1965, p. 7 aThese include salaries and wages, cost of fuel and electricity and ncoSto6f materials and supplies used. Lack of Product Diversification The second major element of the low income problem in the regional dairy subsector is the lack of product diversification at the processing 7Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Quebec, Esquisse du Plan, l'Agriculture, op. cit., pp. 181-85. 59 level. Because of the importance of dairy processing in the provincial food manufacturing industry, it is interesting to take a broad view of this problem. The total production of milk in the Province of Quebec increased from 5,713 million pounds in 1956 to 6,733 million pounds in 1968 (Table 12). During the same period, the quantity of milk absorbed by the fluid milk market decreased from 1,613 to 1,359 million pounds while the quantity used by the manufacturing milk industry increased from 3,553 to 4,981 million pounds. The most significant change which took place during this period was the emergence of cheddar cheese production. The proportion of manufacturing milk utilized for flhe production of cheddar cheese increased from approximately 7 per cent in 1956 to 16 per cent in 1968. Shifts in supply and demand functions have apparently been par- ticularly favorable to dairy farmers producing for the fluid and the cheddar cheese markets. Farm prices increased, on the average, from 2.70 to 3.30 per cwt. of milk for cheese and from 4.50 to 5.79 for fluid milk between 1961 and 1966 for the Province of Quebec as a whole (Table 12). It appears, however, that price increases in the fluid market resulted from increasingly effective supply restrictions. Under these conditions, it seems reasonable to hypothesize that the farmers who sell a large proportion of their production to butter plants had to bear most 6f the hardships which resulted from the substantial increases in total milk supply, expecially after 1967. Farm prices per pound of butterfat decreased from t74.9 in 1964 to £65.3 in 1968. 60 .mcma annm< .oonoEEoo one knumopaH mo unmsunmmon .conuoom Hmnnuasonnw< .Amonnmnuwum mo smonnm .oononov .oomn monumnsmpm spawn was .aoan page .nmsac< .no~-m~ .02 psmonsspu .eonmn>n2 npppunsunpw< .Amunnmnumum mo smonnm connnan .momcmo .mSmuuov .woma one dean .monumnumum znnmn "mounnom monomnnm mnonnm> now on: oEo: haemoe mowsfionHm oHannm>m no: <2 "Honenm an.m cm.m m.ms mam new man aoe.m amm.a. mms.n moan en.m mm m w so mos smm hen 2a<.m nm<.n <2n.s span <2.m anmh owmno>< ucon>nnmm xanz.wmnn9uommnamz .moan as omen .upnono .aonsmunnnua on waaepouo< annz no spasm ppm conuoseonn .mn mamnMumnonH ”a nonwom osmanmomnEannnnunn< " m nonwom oppose "m conmom mnmnomuno u w nonwom amoouum omqnnmconwom "N nonwom cmunaononuoz Hmonucoz one Hmonncoz ”m one o nonwom oocon3mg.um noBOAumman ”H nonwomm .w .m .nooa annmm .oonoEEoo ocm knumnodH mo ucoaunmmon .conuoom Hmnnuasonnw< .monumnumum mo smonsm oonoso .oomH monumnumum Nnnma “oonsom 63 m.m m.~ ~.o~ n.m~ a.a <.mn m.~ o.mn 66an>onn mo owmncoonmm mon.n oas.m see.w~ m<~.6m mna.mn 62a.m~ <6<.m omn.nN “.msn coo.v COH u oDfiOHm new» HmuoH w.nn n.n~ <.mm A.o~ a.m~ s.a~ w.o~ N.- ppnesupn o.n~ 6.nm s.o< o.nm m.n< <.<< a.62 <.nm m.~m m.n6 o.nm m.mm m.oN «.mm n.n6 nmpouoo A.mn n.n6 s.an 6.~n 6.mn n.6m A.mw o.mm nupamuamm o.~a m.n2 n.mm nom.n n.2w ~5p.n sew.n nxmsosne m.mn 06o.n m.~m can.n m<<.n masseuse: H.no Nun m.Hw moo «mm ensue: m.s~ no m.66 mmn 6mm um62-6ammo N.o¢ onH m.Ho How mwa uanuwmmmo <.66 ~62 m.nw mso.n aa~.n pupsap>ss62 Aunoo noav Aunoo noav hunnoo xn nonEnz munnoo kn nonanz HmuoH nunnoo HmuOu no N kuOn «0 N muonoonmihnHmo mo monm mnHunonom msoo monHHE wnHunomom menmm mnmnoo no nonenz .oomH .oonono nnoummm nH munnou up nonenz .muonoonm znnmn mo monm wnHunomom manmm mnmnoo one m3oo wonHHZ wnnunomom manna mnmnoo .menmh mnmnoo HH< .mH MHmHoo one moHuuoo mo oHom osu :uH3 noSuowou muonoonm mnHoo mo oHoo osu uoSu ooonvonn .ouunoonn hnnoo Eonm oonnmnno moB moHoo Houou mo unoo non m.om on once ANV no “muonoonn nnnoo Bonn oonHouno on muonoonm HmnnanoHnwo mo moHom HouOu mo onoE no unoo non o.Hm AHV an menom hnnoo no ooHMHomoHo ono canon HoHonoEEooo .womH onno .AmOHannoum mo noonnm noHnHEoo .ooonoo .osouuov .omouoo .oz ononouoo .oonono .znnnoo up manom HoHonoEEoo now ouoo .anoHHnm Honoomm .onnanoHnw<14eomnoo wo onmnoU oomH "oonnom as; San smaJ 81m nsuon ANMII. new MMMII mMMII. muonoomnaoa 0mm mmm mmm omo mooHunouoan>Hm «mm «mm «on omw menoEHm mum mom «on mum snowmouoz HwH .oou «nu mwn onouoz A 2 3 cu “massage NH mH . Hm ow umoMuonmou um NwH me mow onnuno>onom manna hnHoo muonoonn mnHoo mo nBOQ wonHHE hnnnoo no oonHmmoHo moHom wnHunomom wnHunomom Houoa . menom HoHonoEEoo mo nonanz o.oooH .oonono nnoumom nH hunnou an nonenz .menom unnon no oonmnmmowo menom HoHonoEEoo one muonoonm nnHon mo moHom one o3oo wonHHE wnHunomom menom HoHonoEEoo .oenom HoHonoEEoo ononoo .oH mHmfionsm momsoo vow mofiuasoo Mom magma HmaouoEEoo wow maumh n mamaou mo wou< wow nonesz .ousufioocww4 .mumcmo mo mnmaoo coma "mouaom n.om- oma.o Hmo.a N.oH+ ooH.m Hoo.~ o.m~- oom.o Noo.HH oases m.mm- oao omm.H N.oH+ mam mom o.o~- Hooam. mooqw. moosouoHan o.om- ooo «mo.H o.NH+ oom moo o.oa- oHo.H mso.H anoa-so-ouoo>om ~.~m- ooo.H mso.H o.o~. omo Hoo ~.oa- ooo.H o-.~ oxosoaom m.om- oom oNo.H H.mm+ ANo onm H.o~- moo.H soo.H oaooaoomz o.om- moo How o.om+ now Now o.m~- Now oHH.H mason: s.om- oHN oom ~.Ho- ON on o.om- omu «so uoo3-oaooo o.om- non ooo m.o . om ow m.om- mNo cao oooo-oaooo o.sm- ooo.H oon.H o.Hm. mow ooa o.Nm- oo~.H oom.a ongoao>maoo A N V a s u Manama u n A N v: u pmnesc .u n A N V n n Hones: n u omaooo oooa Hooo mousse .roooa Hooa «moose ooma Hoofi socaou mo mama no wood #90 oumm mahmm HmwouoEEOUuooz mapmw HmwouoEEoo msumm mo honesa Hooch .oooH cam Homa .oonoso auoummm ow kuasoo An manmm HowopoBEoouaoz bum HmwouoEEoo mo Honasz onu aw mowamso .wH mqmm wouawwo3 mum cowwou onu pom mouswwm owwucooummo .ucoo Mom Ho.o cmnu mmoH was owmucoouoa onu umSu moumowocHn .xuowoumo gnu aw mono unmuuanH umoE on“. in.“ accumuomm o.ooH ¢.q H.¢ q.q w.mH ~.om H.m¢ 0mm osofiwom” o.ooH o.m ~.o o.s o.aa o.om ~.os mm: 838368....W o.ooH H.¢ w.H m.m o.NH q.ou «.ma on dsoguscuoumw>flm o.coH m.m m.~ q.¢ m.¢H o.Hm q.mq HRH wxmaoEHm_ o.ooH N.m m.¢ H.m m.HH m.m~ w.o¢ wHH «wowmmumz o.oo~ m.m ¢.N w.~ N.¢H H.mm o.qm ow ocmumz o.ooH w.m m.o H.~ m.NH o.Nm m.mm ma ummzswammu“ o.ooH m.m o.o n: u ¢.m H.wN o.N¢ ma ummmnwnmm0_ o.ooH H.N a.m N.m ~.~H m.~m N.wm on monoco>moom. u I ucoo Mom 1 u Amouom ooo_v r Hmuoe monouo powwow mcamuw ofimum ousummm mm: wcma zucsoo umsuo HH< pom uso pox“: pom sumo amusuHsoHuwm mumo wo>oumefi huosoo >3 mmopo Hafime cu wouo>op HmuOu mo owmuCoouom Hmuoe .ooma .oonoso :uoummm mo hucaoo Np mmouo Hohmz Ou wouo>oo mou< vcmq Honduasofiuw< oo>oudeH .mN mam<9 l ., . :1. vIlI I.. 1 i A 86 indicates that slightly less than 1 per cent of dairy feed concentrates used by regional dairy farmers came from the Prairies.20 The reasons which might explain why so little Prairies feed is used in Eastern Quebec are not entirely clear but it can be argued that price instability is one of them. This was brought into focus by T.C. Kerr, in whose opinion, the implications of closed navigation season and the possibility of a shortage of grain developing in Eastern Canadian points during the winter season are still highly significant in terms of feed grain price instability.21 It would be hazardous to draw generalizations from so little information. The only conclusion which appears to be supported is that the links between dairy feed suppliers and the regional dairy farming industry apparently need to be improved. Credit Market Not only is it difficult to find relevant information concerning the sources of regional dairy feed supply, but it also turns out to be at least as difficult to document the main characteristics of the regional agricultural credit market. It is therefore. hoped that the following observations will partly fill the gap. Two main sources of agricultural credit can be readily identified. The first one is the so-called "Office du Credit Agricdle," a government agency involved in the business of lending money to farmers at a lower 20Compiled from T.C. Kerr, op. cit.,pp. 136-38. It was computed by assuming that regional dairy farmers bought about 5 peroCent of all freight-assisted feed grain shipments transported to the Province of Quebec in 1963-1964 and that the 236,744 cows found on regional commercial dairy farms were fed about 1,000 lbs.of grain concentrates per year. Kerr's study indicates that the 5 per cent assumed above can be viewed as a maximum. 21T.C. Kerr, 0 . cit., pp. 75676. 87 interest rate than private lenders. The second one is mostly made up of private lending institutions. The quantity of credit supplied to local dairymen from each source could not be estimated. A study has been made by Dubé and Martin on the basis of the Office du Crédit Agricole files for the years 1946 to 1956. Their major conclusion was that the most progressive farmers of the region borrowed very little from the government agency and that the main reason given by farmers for borrowing fromthis source was to repay current debts.22 However, there is no basis for determining whether or not this situation still prevails in the region. It might be hypothesized that, because of their low levels of income, a great majority of the dairy farmers in Eastern Quebec have been unable to finance the growth of their dairy enterprise through reinvestment of generated net income. Most of these farmers have apparently borrowed at one time or another on either the private and/or the government credit markets.23 However, the large number of farmers who declared that they wanted to borrow from the government agency in order to repay on-going debts indicates that many regional farmers have not realized the returns that they expected on their agricultural investments. Suppliers of Dairy Equipment and Fertilizer Very little is known about the problems of the regional market for dairy equipments and fertilizer. It would appear that a few 22Yves Dubé and Jean-Marie Martin, op. cit., pp. 153-59 23Ibid., pp. 157-59. 88 regional cooperatives might have been able to bid down the prices of these inputs for their members. A well documented study of the problems of the industries supplying inputs to regional agriculture is needed for determining the extent to which the improvement of their performance might contribute to the well-being of the farmers in the region. It appears very unlikely that regional dairy farming will achieve much higher profitability without a more effective support from both the dairy input supply industry and the dairy processing industry. It appears that a great majority of the regional dairy farmers have persisted in their trade because of government income transfer programs. The main issue which must be raised concerning some regional development planning objectives is whether or not a large proportion of them could thrive while competing with other dairy producing areas of Canada without continual government help. Long-Run Objectives and Comparative Advantage. The thrust of planning in market economies must be the promotion of economic activities which can hold on their own under free market conditions. One of the main, and usually most difficult, tasks of planners is therefore to predict comparative advantage in the economic activities which they attempt to promote. The ensuing discussion con- siders the planning issues in the dairy subsector of Eastern Quebec within this perspective. Distinction Between Fluid and Manufacturing Milk A major distinction is made at the outset between fluid milk and manufacturing milk. For the dairy industry which supplies fluid 89 milk, the end product, because of its relatively high transportation costs and perishability, dictates that the fluid milk industry will locate relatively close to markets. The manufacturing milk industry on the other hand does not appear to be as closely tied to markets. Its location depends upon a number of factors, including, a steady and adequate supply of milk and/or cream from dairy farms, the avails ability of labor, concentration of the industry to the extent that it determine whether ornotcrpuimum size processing plants can be achieved in a specific region, adequate transportation services and many other factors. In the Province of Quebec, Montreal has a fairly large milkshed which appears to extend farther away year after year. Quebec city and the few other smaller urban centers also receive the bulk of their fluid milk supply from their surrounding rural communities. It might reasonably be expected that the dairy farmers of Eastern Quebec will not be able to penetrate these major urban fluid milk markets in the foreseeable future, unless the farmers of these two major milksheds are presented with and take further opportunities of restricting supply in order to bid up the price of fluid milk within these areas. Even under these circumstances, however, greater collective action (which is in the offing) would very unlikely create interregional price discrepancies such that one might consider the possibility of competitively trans- porting milk from Eastern Quebec to Montreal for instance. Under current conditions the area supplied by fluidlmilkwprbducedsnofrEasternf Quebec includes the totality of the small urban markets of the region 90 itself, a growing market on the so-called North Shore of Quebec and marginal entries into some adjacent areas. It is expected that the dairy farmers of Eastern Quebec will be able to supply this fluid milk market at less costs than any other agricultural region of Canada in the foreseeable future. A detailed discussion of the nature and the size of this market is in a later section of this chapter. For the dairy industry which supplies manufacturing milk, the situation is much more ambiguous. It is appropriate to recall that 95 per cent of all milk produced in the region in 1963 (300 million out of 313 million lbs) was processed into butter. The question which naturally arises at this point is the following: Can the continuance of this industry in the region be explained in terms of the theory of comparative advantage? Regional Comparative Advantage in Dairying On the basis of Haberler's formulation of the theory of compara- tive advantage one might hypothesize that Eastern Quebec devotes a substantial quantity of its resources to produce butter because the cost of producing butter in terms of alternative commodities foregone is currently less in this region than in the other regions of Canada which do not produce this commodity or which devote a decreasing amount of resources to this commodity.24 It is appropriate to introduce a clarification at this stage. This clarification has to do with the fact that this study compares Eastern Quebec with the rest of Quebec 24G. Haberler, The Theory of International Trade (London: Hodge, 1963). 9D and Canada. It therefore arbitrarily excludes the United States as competitor. The only justification for this exclusion is that butter is a highly protected commodity in Canada. As a result of an embargo set up by the Canadian government, butter. is sold in Canada at a price at least twice higher than the current world price. Challenging this policy is beyond the scope of this research. It is therefore accepted as a statement of fact which is likely to prevail in the foreseeable future. In order to substantiate the comparative advantage of the region in agriculture, we first rely upon the following excerpts of arguments advanced by the planners: The final option is based on the belief that the various types of farm production should be regionalized in Quebec, where each would specialize in the type of production in which it has a comparative advantage. Since forage crops can be used equally well for dairy production or beef-cattle raising, a choice must be made between the two. However, if the long-run increases in production within a region are to some extent proportional to the natural advantages of that region, it appears that the Pilot Region (Eastern Quebec) should specialize in dairy rather than beef production. There is a tendency for the raising of beef cattle to be concentrated more and more in the Western Provinces while, in dairying, Quebec and Ontario continue in the lead. Moreover, Quebec has been gaining relatively, while Ontario has declined. Since the objective of the "Bureau d'Aménagement de l'Est du Québec" is to make intensive use of all production factors while ensuring an adequate income, development efforts should be towards the dairy industry. . . . It should be added that the reorganization of agriculturelwill decrease the number of farmers, and hence will impose the need to create enough jobs in other sectors. The substitution of beef for milk would greatly accentuate this problem. Total conversion of the dairy industry to livestock raising would bring about a further decrease of about 4,000 individuals classified as farmers.25 25Development Plan for the Pilot Region, A Summary, op. cit., p. 41, 46 and 47. ”9:3er 92 Two major preoccupations of the planners are carried by these statements. The first one has to do with the choice of agricultural strategies which would be consistent with the agricultural comparative advantage of the region. The second one has to do with the labor dis- placement effect of the alternative strategies which could satisfy the requirements of regional comparative advantage. As far as their first preoccupation is concerned, the planners argue that the past trends in agricultural resources allocation by Provinces of Canada indicate that Quebec's share of the national dairy market has been increasing. Evidence shows that this argument is true. Quebec's share of total milk production in Canada went from 33 per cent in 1950 to 36.7 per cent in 1964.26 However, no data are available to determine whether or not Eastern Quebec's share of the national production has been increasing over time. This study submits that Strictly valid con- clusions on comparative advantage cannot be reached on the basis of past trends alone. This is especially true with respect to both dairying and cattle feeding where government intervention has been such that the monetary costs of production can no longer be equated with the real costs to the economy. On the basis of the previous discussion on the nature of the problems in the regional dairy subsector, it appears that regional agriculture has become heavily specialized in butter production because of its relatively low costs of producing butter in terms of alternatives 26T. G. Kerr, op. cit., p. 99. _____;_ 93 foregone.27 It is interesting to note on that respect that total industrial employment in the region decreased from 6,096 in 1949 to 5,739 in 1965.28 Under these circumstances, it may be argued that the regional dairy processing industry had little difficulty to attract labor services at relatively low wages as well as to buy manufacturing milk at relatively low prices. :4- - .j'.‘ H By combining the various characteristics of the regional dairy subsector it appears possible to explain the presence and the contin- uance of butter production in Eastern Quebec in the following manner. 'W‘mt .- : Butter production is known to be a highly seasonal economic activity in Canada (Table 13). This structural characteristicsof the dairy industry implies that butter factories must be able to attract labor mostly during the summer season. The supply of labor is not likely to come from the dairy farming population since the farmers are also producing at their peak levels during the same period. From the point of view of entrepreneung it would appear that an advantageous location consists of a region where both raw materials and labor services can 27Trant argues the following: "In recent years, the number of dairy cows has been increasing in the Province of Quebec, but de- clining in most others. This has been attributed to the limited alternatives available to Quebec farmers, who have been faced with a short growing season more suitable for forage production than for the fattening of livestock. Consequently, while most Canadian dairy producers would be hurt by free (international) trade, Quebec producers, because of their limited alternatives, would be more likely to remain in dairying than producers in other provinces." In Gerald I. Trant, David L. MacFatlane and Lewis A. Fisher, Trade Liberalization and Canadian Agriculture (University of Toronto Press), published for the Private Planning Association of Canada, 1968, p. 54. 28Growth Patterns in Manufacturing Employment by Counties and Census Divisions,,1949-1959/1961-1965 (Ottawa, Canada, Dominion Bureau GP Statistics), Catalogue no. 31—503, Occasional, October, 1969, pp. 24" 31 o 94 be bought at the lowest price, given that such a location does not involve transportation costs which more than offset the relative advan- tage in production. This appears to be of special importance for the smaller firms as far as the cost of labor is concerned (Table 26). As a matter of fact a considerable amount of verbal information spread throughout the technical studies made in the region indicates that the regional butter plants have been paying somewhat lower wage rates and lower prices for their milk than the plants located in other areas of the country with advanced dairy industry. The relatively high level of seasonal unemployment in Eastern Quebec as well as the marked ten- dency for regional dairy farming to depend largely on utilization of summer grazing are consistent with these findings. TABLE 26 Hourly Wages in Butter and Cheese Factories by Group Based on Value of Sales, Canada, 1962. Average Hourly Size Groups Man Hours Paid Wages Wages (11 (2) (2/1) ($'000) ('000 hours) ($‘000) ($/hour) Under 10 6 5 0.83 10 to 24.9 22 23 1.05 25 to 49.9 130 146 1.12 50 to 99.9 481 536 1.11 100 to 199.9 1,382 1,580 1.14 200 to 499.9 2,854 3,439 1.20 500 to 999.9 2,006 2,533 1.26 1,000 to 4,999.9 3,739 5,068 1.36 5,000 and over 1,127 1,807 1.60 TOTAL 11,748 15,137 1.29 Source: Dairy Factories,_l962 (Ottawa, Canada, Dominion Bureau of Statistics), Catalogue No. 32-309, June 1965. 95 Can Regional Comparative Advantage in Dairying be Maintained? An important planning issue in the region consists in the fact that current regional comparative advantage in dairying must be attri- buted to low factor costs rather than to relative physical efficiency in production. If the current comparative advantage of butter plants in the region can be partly explained by lower factor costs due to low opportunity cost of the people supplying these factors, a relevant question which naturally arises is the following: To what extent can this comparative advantage be maintained in the future if the planning effort is successful in its broad attempt to raise the opportunity of the neépLae supplying labor services and milk? The answer is that this comparative advantage is likely to be lost unless a major breakthrough is achieved in raising the technical efficiency of both the butter plants and the dairy farms supplying the raw material to these plants. The dairy development strategies proposed by the planners are genuinely oriented towards this objective. Discussing whether or not this break- through may be achieved in the regional dairy processing industry is beyond the scope of this study. In conclusion it appears that there is a substantial potential for efficiency improvements in the regional dairy subsector and that the planners were probably right in arguing that dairy development strategies oriented towards both the milk processors and the dairy farmers would be more likely to succeed than dairy farming development 96 projects alone. Dairy Farming was retained by the planners as the sector of agricultural activity which will most likely continue to justify its presence in the region in the foreseeable future.29 The belief that dairy farming is likely to become a more profit- able activity under the impetus of the development projects is based, however, on the assumption that the dairy farmers will react to these policies according to the planners' expectations. It is our own belief that the dairy farmers of Eastern Quebec will respond to these policies according to their individual interests in the same way that they have rationally responded in the past to the environment and the government policies which directly or indirectly affected the conduct of their business. The belief that economically depressed areas are inhabited by economically non-motivated people has persisted to some extent in Quebec. This belief has crept into the planners' arguments. However, the assumption of economic rationality on the part of the participants in the regional dairy subsector has not been carefully examined. 29Discussion presented in this section reaches an agreement with the planners--and with Trant (see footnote 26)--over the argument that a region like Eastern Quebec has but a limited number of alternatives in agriculture. This study submits, however, that one long-run alter- native which deserves some further attention is that of raising cattle in Eastern Quebec. Such research would need to compare two sub- alternatives. The first one would involve raising cattle to maturity in the region. The second alternative would consist in raising starters ohatiwouldlbezexported to grain-crop regions where they would be fed to maturity. The former sub-alternative has been given some consideration by the planners of Eastern Quebec but the latter has not. 97 Economic Rationality in the Regional Dairy Subsector It has been said again and again that people in poor communities do not care to maximize the returns accruing to the factors of production which they own, including their labor services. The following are excerpts of arguments drawn from the regional planning documents which carry this belief: The first reason for the region's lag is marginality caused by difficult bio-physical conditions, distance from important urban markets, and the higher cost of supply that distance imposes. Another reason is that the farm is not always regarded as an economic enterprise that should be profitable . . . Present farm structures are not properly balanced; the production factors of land, labor and capital are not combined to give the best results.30 However, it is possible to account for much of the poverty in regional agriculture without assuming that it is partly due to lack of economic motivation.31 Those who argue lack of economic motivation need to demonstrate resource adjustmentsstriCtlyMunder the farmers' control «dfiafllwould increase output significantly with due regard to (l) the current physical and institutional environments within which they have to operate, and (2) the present input and output price levels in the regional dairy subsector. The hypothesis advanced in this study is to the contrary, namely the poverty in the regional dairy subsector must be attributed to the inadequate resources (including human resources) from which these farm owners seek to obtain as much 30Development Plan for the Pilot Region, A Summary, op. cit., pp. 42 and 44. 31The word "assumption" is purposedly used in this statement because nobody has yet proved that these people lack economic motivation. 98 income as they can. The approach of the following discussion is to apply the concepts of production economics to show that low resources productivity in the rggional dairy subsector is not necessarily due to lack of economic motivation. The discussion is restricted to the butter plants and the dairy farms, the two major users of production factors in the regional dairy subsector. The Butter Factories An example illustrates the complexity of cost conditions in butter processing which can explain why small high unit cost plants might have persisted in Eastern Quebec. Butter production was shown to be a highly seasonal activity in the region. As a matter of fact, regional data showed that the peak-production (June) of butter was about fourteen times as large as the through-production (February) in 1966 (Table 14). under such circumstances, it makes little sense to think of butter plants operators in Eastern Quebec as trying to minimize the cost of a given output steadily and regularly to be produced. Stigler suggests that the objective of such firms faced with significant problems of output instability is rather to minimize the cost of a probability distribution of outputs, the probability distribution indicating the fraction of time each output is expected to be produced. He shows that the desire to obtain output flexibility might make horizontal short-run marginal cost curves a deliberate objective of maximizing behaviour on the part of those firms faced with such problems.32 32George Stigler, "Production and Distribution in the Short-Run", Journal of Political Economy, June, 1939, pp. 312-22. 99 The lack of data on costs of production of butter plants in Eastern Quebec prevented use of "real" cost curves to demonstrate the validity of this theory. Suppose, however, that a butter plant in (Easterh Quebec can choose between a method of production A which is very rigid and highly efficient for a particular level of output and a method of production B which is considered as a flexible but less efficient method of production (Figure 3). Let the horizontal axis denote the average butter output per month and curves A and B the average variable cost curves for methods A and B respectively. The monthly distribution of the output over the year may be such that the operator makes more profit whth method B than he might with method A. It is notzclear that this hypothetical case would apply directly to the current situations of any of butter plants in Eastern Quebec. 1: - , marginal Marginal cost curve / cost per \ for technology A /’ pound of \ // butter \ / I Marginal cost curve for technology B / / S —1 Average quantity produced per month FIGURE 3. Hypothetical Marginal Cost Curves for two Different Techno- logies of Butter Production. 100 However, there are reasons to believe that Stigler's argument is of great relevance for the problem at hand.33 If in fact one or more methods of production of type A are avail- able to and known by the region's butter plant operators, it may still be economically justifiable not to adopt these methods until greater monthly stability in output is achieved. Therefore, comparing resources I use efficiency on these plants with that of plants in other areas such as the Mbntreal region where monthly output instability appears to be less than in Eastern Quebec (Table 14) must not lead one to conclude that the former are not attempting to minimize costs of production. It only allows one to conclude that the environments of both regions are substantially different and that changing those elements of the environ- ment which cause greater monthly output instability might be one of the important conditions for further cost decreases in butter plants of Eastern Quebec. Dairy Farmers A major basis for assuming irrationality in resource alloca- tions on dairy farms is the observation that significantly different patterns of resource uses are employed. However, empirical studies on the economies of production in dairy farming and the asset fixity theory show that such differences in resource combinations do not necessarily imply lack of economic motivation. 33It can be suggested that the dairy processing industry is an "ideal" case where Stigler's hypothesis could be tested. It would be interesting to rank dairy processing tehcnologies along either a capital-intensity or a labor-intensity continuum and determine under what conditions one technology is more competitively efficient than another. The data which are necessary for testing this hypothesis are not currently available in Quebec. 101 Variable Factors Many empirical studies of production functions for dairy cows have been made in the United States.34 All of them tend to show that the isoquants of the forage substitution relationship have relatively small curvature. Frick and Mighell have concluded, on the basis of the earliest studies, that The near linearity of the isoquants of the forage substitution relationship and the annual total milk response curve both seem to indicate that the combinations of feed inputs and levels of production can be widely shifted with no great effect on profits . . . The fact that we do have extreme variations in quantity and quality of feeds consumed by milk cows and a great array of skills and experience among dairymen is some evidence that a considerable variation in feeding dairy cows is within the limits of economic tolerance. It thus appears that definite conclusionslon the relative effic- Ciency of variable resources use on dairy farms are difficult to reach. This is especially true of cases where self-feeding of pasture and hay, made possible by low land prices, saves considerable labor costs in a region like Eastern Quebec while a substantially higher price for land might not allow this practice to be pursued to the same 34The results of the earliest studies are summarized in G.A. Frick and R.L. Mighell, Adequncy_gf Dairy Feedipg Input-Output Research Data from the Point of View of the Economist, published in "Nutritional and Economic Aspects of Feed Utilization by Dairy Cows? edited by C.R. Hoglund, Glenn L. Johnson, Charles A. Lassiter and L.D..Mccilliard (Ames: Iowa State College Press), 1959, pp. 107- 115. More recent estimates can be found in Leo M. Hoover et als. "Economic Relationship of Hay and Concentrate Consumption to Milk Pro- duction," Journal of Farm Economics, vol. IL, no. 1, Part I, February, 1967, pp. 64-78. 35G.E. Frick, et als.,op, cit., p. 114. 102 extent in a region like Montreal. Fixed Assets Let us shift our attention to the allocation of the so-called fixed assets on dairy farms. G.L. Johnson defines a fixed asset as onefnr' which the marginal value productivity in its present use is greater than its disposal price and smaller than its replacement cost.36 This definition is adopted in this study. Johnson's asset fixity theory is essentially based upon the recognition that some factor markets are imperfect for agriculture in general and.morenso‘for acme um‘ specific segments of the agricultural sector. It is appropriate for this study to extend this statement a little further and argue that some agricultural factor markets may be more imperfect in some regions of a country than in others in the sense that the difference between the acquisition price and the salvage value of a given factor may be larger in the former than in the latter. The following discussion explores the implications of such a theory for resource allocation on Eastern Quebec's dairy farms. *pr the sake of brevity, Johnson's logical derivation of fixed asset theory is not restated in this study.37 However, in order to 36G.L. Johnson, "Supply Function--Some Facts and Notions," Agri- cultural Adjustment Problems in a Growing Economy (Ames: Iowa State College Press, 1958), p. 78. 37A clear and concise explanation of this theory can be found in Dale E. Hathaway, op. cit., pp. 110-18. DOB. show that this theory applies, we first need to examine the possibility of a significant difference between acquisition cost and salvage value for one or more inputs used on a given regional dairy farm at a given point in time.38 Two inputs which come readily to one's mind are labor and land. For an individual already engaged in dairy farming in the region, the acquisition cost for his labor measured, as of 1969, would be the opportunity cost of the income foregone by not entering another occupation at the time he entered dairy farming. On the other hand, the salvage value of his labor from the dairy farm, as of 1969, is essentially the earnings thatEhe«couldvreceiue lae derived from these programs would in itself constitute a major 133 research study.10 This study is restricted to analyzing the likely consequences of the alternative dairy development strategies described as strategies I, II, and III. It is necessary to recognize that significant improvements in the dairy farmers managerial ability might be achieved in the region because of the implementation of strategies which are not considered in this study. Such improvements might substantially contribute to increasing these farmers' capacity to discover and select between new dairy income opportun- v.1: ities. The fact is, however, that these farmers are now faced with a choice of either making a positive response or making no response whatsoever to some specific regional dairy development programs. Some evidence on the intentions of a selected group of regional dairy farmers with regard to these programs is presented in the following pages. The Regional Dairy Farmers' Intentions One of the main objectives of this research is to find out how a dairy farmer in a given situation is most likely to react to the new 10Two major difficulties may be anticipated by the researchers who would undertake such a study. First, almost all the relevant data will have to be collected through survey. Secondly, the uncertainty concern- ing the future orientation of the federal milk subsidy program would greatly affect the confidence limit for the estimates obtained. For instance, the potential market price increases received by the regional dairy farmers because of product diversification at the processing level might be readily erased by a reduction in subsidies. The latest changes in the federal milk price policy indicate that a gradual return to,a freer milk market might be forthcoming in Canada. Predicting when and how fast these changes are going to take place is an intractable problem. in. a 134 government programs. The likely response of the regional dairy farmers to the new programs may be classified as follows: 1) farmers who continue in dairying and make a positive response to the new dairy development opportunities; 2) farmers who continue in dairying but make no response to the new dairy development opportunities; 3) farmers who opt to leave dairying as a result of exit oppor- tunities in the new government programs or for other reasons. The empirical evidence presented in the following parts of this 1'1. . '. study covers a limited segment of the total number of regional farms reporting dairy enterprises. It is therefore necessary to begin this discussion by placing the surveyed population in the perspective of the total population. The Surveyed Population Seventy-eight Eastern Quebec dairy farmers were surveyed in the summer of 1969. Each farmer participated in a personal interview in which he was asked a series of questions including some regarding the future growth potentials of his dairy enterprise as he perceives them and the most likely course of action that he intends to follow in order to make his dairy enterprise more profitable. The farms included in the survey were not selected on a probability sample basis.11 As a result, these farms are not necessarily representa- tive of all the commercial dairy farmers in the region. There is unsuf- 118ee appendix A for details on the design and execution of the survey. The original questionnaire can be found in appendix A. 135 ficient information available on a probability sample basis for Eastern Quebec commercial dairy farms to permit an estimate of the extent to which the estimates presented in this study tend to approximate, or to diverge from, the estimates that would result from information on a probability sample of all regional commercial dairy farms. Ffi’ The criteria which were used to select the communities where the survey was conducted are explained in details in Appendix A. These criteria are likely to result in a sample of commercial dairy farms from 1 ET _ which limited inferences can be drawn about commercial dairy farms located within the two major regional milksheds. Commercial dairy farms located within the boundaries of these two milksheds probably have more adequate resources than other commercial dairy farmers in the region. The likeli- hood that they will continue farming may be fairly high. It is therefore necessary to emphasize that the farms surveyed are not necessarily repre- % sentative of other strata within the regional dairy farming industry. General Results The results of the survey indicate that a high proportion (62.8 per cent) of the respondents intend to increase both the size and the production capacity of their dairy herds. A third of the respondents said that they intend to increase the production capacity of their herds but that they do not plan to milk more cows in the next five years (Table 28). This leaves a small minority (3.9 per cent) of respondents who wish to either leave dairying or continue in dairy farming with the same number and the same type of cows.. 136 TABLE 28. Respondents' Intentions Concerning Their Dairy Farming Enterprises. Number of Percentage of Respondents Specified Strategy Respondents in each category (number) (percentage) Increase herd size and production capacity of cows 49 62.8 Increase production capacity of cows only 26 33.3 Increase herd size only 0 0.0 No change planned 1 1.3 Leave dairying _2 , 2.6 TOTAL 78 100.0 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. Most of these farmers thus seem to recognize that increases in either dairy herd sizes or in production yields of cows (or both) might significantly contribute to improving their income situation. There is substantial disagreement, however, among the respondents as to how they should go about increasing the size and the yield of their dairy herds. On the one hand, a large majority (85.7 per cent) of the respondents who wish to increase the size of their dairy herds intend to raise their own heifers (Table 29). A rather small minority (14.3 per cent) of the respondents wish to buy either all of or only some of their new heifers. 137 On the other hand, a slight majority (61.3 per cent) of the respondents who declare that they want to increase the yield of their cows believe that they can achieve this objective by improving the quality of their sires and thereby raise cows with higher production capacity (Table 30).. This belief is shared, to some extent, by a smaller proportion of the respondents (22.7 per cent) who feel that they also need to increase feeding rations in order to achieve this objective. A smaller group of farmers (8.0 per cent) intend to raise heifers with higher production capacity and to improve feeding rations but fail to mention how they expect to go about raising more productive cows. All other respondents (8.0 per cent) would apparently resort to buying all of or some of their replacement animals, in conjunction with some combination of other strategies, in order to increase the yield of their dairy herds. These results raise some serious questions concerning the estab- lishment of specialized dairy-stock-raising farms in the region. Apparently some deep reluctance towards shifting from a raising-own-replacements strategy to a buying-replacements strategy might be expected on the part of a large majority of these regional dairy farmers. Two factors might, however, substantially contribute to reducing their reluctance. First, lowering the price of the heifers (possibly through a subsidy) to be sold by the specialized dairy-stock-raisers might be expected to increase the number of buyers. Secondly, a momentum for adoption of buying- replacements strategy might build up over time if (1) the early adopters thereby significantly increased the productivity and the profitability of f, . -:.':" {We .‘ 138 TABLE 29. Respondents Favoring a Specific Strategy for Increasing Size of Herds, Number and Percentage. Number of Percentage of Respondents Specified Strategy Respondents in Each Category (number) (percentage) Raise all replacement 5; cows on own farms 42 85.7 ; Buy all replacement cows 5 10.2 ’ Raise and buy replace- : ment cows 2 4.1 ; 1 TOTAL 49 100 .0 j 2 .1: Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. TABLE 30. Respondents Favoring a Specific Combinatirnxof Strategies for Increasing Yields of Dairy Herds, Number and Percentage. Specified Combination Number of Percentage of Respondents of Strategies Respondents in Each Category (number) (percentage) Improve quality of own sires and raise more productive heifers on farm 46 61.3 Improve quality of own sires, feed more hay and grains and raise more productive heifers on own farm 17 22.7 Feed more hay and grains and raise more productive heifers on own farm 6 8.0 Feed more hay and grains and buy new heifers 3 4.0 Buy all or some of the new heifers ._§ 4.0 TOTAL 75 100.0 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farm Survey, 1969. 139 their enterprises, and (2) the gains accruing to the adOpters become vis- ible to the non-adopters. The results of the survey confirm none the less- that a significant group of respondents (24.4 per cent) might shift either partially or totally to a buying replacements strategy in the coming years.12 Some evidence also indicates that this group of farmers would make a positive response to reductions in the price of heifers sold by the specialized dairy-stock raisers (Table 31). It hardly needs to be pointed out, however, that a strategy which 1. Ins-ii. 't’ ' A would allow these dairy farmers to raise more productive heifers on their own farms might gain wider and faster acceptance among them than a general- ized buying replacement strategy, especially if purchases of more productive heifers were not subsidized. These findings strongly suggest that arti- ficial insemination may be one of the most suitable alternatives to recommend for the region. Conforming to the general organization of this research, the following discussion presents some evidence on the likely response of regional dairy farmers to this alternative before analysing its economic consequences. The results of the survey indicate that a majority (52.6 per cent) of the respondents have used artificial insemination in the past and will probably continue to use it in the future, especially if its cost decreases (Table 32). A few of the respondents (5.1 per cent) have used it in the past and said they will not use it in the future even if it becomes less expensive. The most astonishing finding, however, 12This comprises 8 per cent of the respondents who generally favor a buying-replacement strategy (Table 30) plus 16.4 per cent of the res- pondents who do not generally favor a buying-replacement strategy but who might shift to it if the price of heifers sold by specialized dairy-stock raisers is not higher than $250. 140 TABLE 31. Number of Heifers that Some Local Dairymen Might Buy Per Year from the Dairy Stock Raisers at Various Prices.a Average Number of Heifers Likely Price of Heifers to be Bought Per Farm Per Year $250 $200 $100 O‘DJN n J " «A .14 aBased on 19 respondents' answers. bRound numbers. Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. ‘mae'imn7__ ‘ . ' I TABLE 32. Respondents Holding Specified Opinion Concerning Artificial Insemination, Number and Percentage. Number of Percentage of Respondents Speéified Opinions Respondents In Each Category Has used A.I. in the past and will probably use it in the future, especially if less expensive 41 52.6 Never used A.I. in the past and will probably not use it in the future, even if less expensive 32 41.0 Has used AJI. in the past but will probably not use it in the future even if less expensive 4 5.1 Never used A.I. in the past but will probably use it in the future if less expensive _1 1.3 TOTAL 78 100.0 Source: Eastern Quesbec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. 141 has to do with the relatively high proportion (41.0 per cent) of res- pondents who said that they never used artificial insemination in the past and will probably not use it in the foreseeable future even ifl” it becomes less expensive. As a matter of fact, only one respondent declared that he never used it in the past but would probably give it a try if it became less expensive. Some 43 out of 45 respondents who declared having used artificial insemination in the past said that they paid $5.00 per cow serviced. Some 32 out of 42 respondents who said that they will probably use it in the future if it becomes less expensive ex- auq-t-flal InlJ. - 11;). 1- pressed the opinion that $3.00 per cow serviced would seem a reasonable price for them. It must also be pointed out that, apparently, none of ' those respondents who have used artificial breeding in the past has completely shifted to this practice, witness the fact that all of them still own one or two dairy sires. These finding on the respondents' apparent opinions concerning artificial insemination bring forth the following remarks. There are reasons to suspect that the adoption of artificial breeding might have impinged upon some serious barrier in the region. However no evidence is available for confirming whether or not this barrier can be associated with either a general lack of education or with some serious sociélogical and religious hindrances, but it appears that improvements in technical information might substantially contribute to more widespread adoption among the regional dairy farmers. It has been argued that dairymen in thinly populated and/0t remote areas of countries where A.I. became firmly established still continue 142 to prefer natural service.13 The facts which could explain this situa- tion havetot yet been adequately investigated but it appears that the conditions of supply of A.I. services in these areas might be relatively deficient when compared to areas located near major urban centers. It is thought that poor supply conditions may be as important as factors related to demand conditions in explaining the low level of adoption of A.I. services by dairy farmers in remote areas of countries with ‘LILO 151.1.” . advanced dairying. The very scatter and low density of cows in such areas probably makes it costly or unprofitable for the inseminators. This factor is important because the services of the inseminator must be available within the specified period of time when cows are in heat for A.I. to be profitable. Supply and demand conditions notwithstanding, the fact remains that the appeal of alternative breeding methods to dairymen varies from one dairy operation to another. The following section attempts to determine whether the response of a regional dairy farmer to alternative dairy development strategies is likely to be related to the current size and milk yield of his dairy herd. Factors Associated with the Reppondents' Preferences It may tentatively be argued that the farmers' response to alter- native dairy development strategies is likely to differ significantly on farms of different herd sizes and of different levels of productivity as measured by the herd's average milk production per cow. These hypo- theses are based on four presumptions. First, operators with relatively 131. Micheal Lerner and H.P. Donald, Mbdern Development in Animal Breeding, (London; Academic Press, Inc., 1966), p. 137. 143 large herds are expected to be more innovative and more financially secure than other dairy farmers in the region. Secondly, operators with relatively large herds are expected to have greater managerial capacities than other regional farmers. Thirdly, respondents who already own the most productive dairy herds are expected to more likely continue to raise their own dairy replacements then other respondents. Fourthly, operators with relatively large dairy herds are expected to be in a preferable position to assume whatever risks a dairy herd expansion strategy might currently entail. As expected, the results concerning the respondents' preference for higher dairy herd expansion or no herd expansion during the next five years support the hypothesis that current dairy herd size may be an important factor associated with the decision to expand the size of the dairy enterprise (Table 33). As a matter of fact, the results show that respondents with average (18 to 25 cows) and relatively large (26 cows or more) dairy herds are almost equally likely to favor a dairy herd expansion strategy whereas the respondents with relatively small herds (17 cows or less) are less likely to favor expansion.14 The overall results, however, fail to support the hypothesis that current average dairy herd production per cow may be an important factor assoc- iated with the decision to expand or not to expand the size of the dairy enterprise (Table 34). This finding sounds astonishing, especially with regard to the factual evidence indicating that one is more likely 14It is interesting to note that respondents favoring expansion appear to be distributed according to a bimodal probability function. 144 TABLE 33. Respondents in three Dairy Herd Size Categories Who are Likely to Either Expand or not Expand Herd Size in the Next Five Years, Number and Percentage.8 M Herd Sizegfinumber of cows) Favored Strategy 17 or less 18-25 26 or more Total Number of farmers 33 31 14 78 ‘M‘ - - - z - - - Expand herd size 45.5 77.4 71.4 62.8 Not expand herd size 54.5 22.6 28.6 37.2 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969 ' I m'nt ' 3A two-way chi-square test between herd size and the decision.bo either expand or not expand herd size is significant at the 0.05 level of test. The calculated value of the Chi-square was 6.31 compared to 5.00 at the five percentage point of the Chi-square distribution with two degrees of freedom. Thus the null hypothesis that tne two factors are indepen- dent must be rejected at that level of the test. TABLE 34. Respondents in Three Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production Per Cow Likely to Either Expand or not Expand Herd Size, Number and Percentage.a A: Average 1968 Dairy Herd Production Per Cow Favored Strategy less than 6,000 6,000-6,999 7,000 or more Total Number of Farmers 227 34 22 78 7. _____ Expand herd size 54.6 70.6 59.1 62.8 Not expand herd size 45.4 29.4 40.9 37.2 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Earns Survey, 1969. aA two-way Chi-square test between average herd production per cow and the decision to either expand or not expand herd size is not significant at the 0.05 level of test. The calculated value of Chi-Square was 1.61 compared to 5.99 at the five percentage point of the Chi-Square distri- bution with two degrees of freedom. Thus the null hypothesis that the two factors are independent cannot be rejected at the level of the test. 145 to find the most productive dairy herds on farms with relatively large herds than on those with relatively small herds (Table 35). It may also be hypothesized that dairy herd size and present herd productivity may be important factors associated with the respondents' likely decision to pursue one the following options: (1) keeping on raising their own replacement cows by natural service, or (2) buying | some or all of their replacement cows, or (3) keeping on raising all replacements animals while attempting to breed more productive cows through more frequent use of artificial insemination. However, the 1“: .'i results of the survey'fmfl to support the hypotheses that dairy herd sizes (Table 36) and average herd yields per cow (Table 37) may be important factors associated with the respondents' expressed preference for either one of these options. This implies that present herd sizes and present herd productivity are not strong bases for predicting which dairy herd expansion and/or improvement strategy might be preferred by a given dairy farmer. The overall results thus lead to the following conclusion. As expected, the survey results indicate that the respondents with rela- tively large dairy herds (18 or more) are likely to further expand their dairy enterprise than respondents with relatively small dairy herds (less than 17 cows). The overall results, however, fail to support the hypotheses that current herd sizes and current average herd yields per cow are related to the respondents' expressed preference for alternative means to expand their dairy enterprise. In conclusion it appears that the respondents with relatively small herds tend toefiknv greater reluctance to further commit themselves 146 TABLE 35. Respondents in Three Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production Per Cow Reporting a Specified Herd Size, Number and Percentage.8 Herd Size Average 1968 dairygherd production per cow (Number of Cows) less than 6,000 6,000-6,999 7,000 or more Total Number of Farmers 22 34 22 78 - _ Z - - 17 or less 63.6 50.0 18.2 44.8 18-25 31.8 35.3 45.4 37 2 26 or more 4.6 14.7 36.4 18 0 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. aA two-way Chi-square test between herd size and average herd yield per cow (combining thelast two rows in order to avoid having last row cell frequencies less than 5) is significant at the 0.05 level of test. The calculated value of Chi-square was 9.82 compared to 5.99 at the five percentage point of the Chiwsquare distribution with two degrees of freedom. Thus the null hypothesis that the two factors are independent must be rejected at that level of the test. TABLE 36. Respondents in Two Dairy Herd Size Categories Who Tend to Favor Specified Practices, Number and Percentage.a Herd Size Specified Strategy Will probably Will probably Will probably Total use A.I. more buy some of or continue to intensively all new re- raise all repla- placements cements on own farm with natu- ral service No. of Respondents 4(35) (20) (23) (78) - - Z _ - 17 or less 45.7 40.0 39.1 42.3 18 or more 54.3 60.0 60.9 57.7 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. aA two-way Chi~square test between herd size and likely decision to pur- sue a given strategy is not significant at the 0.05 level of test. The calculated value of Chi-square was 0.34 compared to 5.99 at the five percentage point of the Chi-square distribution with two degrees of freédom.'Fhus the null hypothesis that the two factors are independent cannot be rejected at that level of the test. 147 TABLE 37. Respondents in Two Classes of Average 1968 Herd Production Per Cow Who Tend to Favor Specified Practices, Number and Percentage.8 Will probably continue to Average 1968 raise all dairy herd Will probably replacements production Will probably buy some of on own farm per cow Use A.I. more or all new with natural (pounds) intensively replacements service Total Number of Respondents 35 20 23 78 - - Z - - 6,500 or less 51.4 50.0 52.2 51.3 more than 6,500 48.6 50.0 47.8 48.7 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Earmv“Sflrvey, 1969. 3A two-way Chi-square test between average herd production per cow and likely decision to pursue a given strategy is not significant at the 0.05 level of test. The calculated value of Chi—Square was 0.03 com- pared to 5.99 at the five percentage point of the Chi-square distribu- tion with two degrees of freedom. Thus the null hypothesis that the two factors are independent cannot be rejected at that level of the test. to dairy farming than those respondents with relatively large dairy herds.15 Determining whether the small dairymen are actually holding back from investing in dairying while waiting for favorable changes in exit opportunities is beyond the scope of this research. 15The farmer's age is probably an important factor related to these differences. This factor was not considered in this study but the conclusions presented in this section indicate that one might need to give it some consideration in order to explain differences in the regional farmers' intentions. 148 It hardly needs to be emphasized that the survey results fail to clearly indentify a single group of strategies which a large majority of the regional dairy farmers might adhere to in the short run. The variety of beliefs concerning the most appropriate combination of means for increasing net income from dairying in the region raises some in. serious questions concerning the relative merit of alternative combi- nations of dairy development strategies as perceived by the farmers . themselves.16 This study puts forward the argument that one of the j I following three situations might exist which could partly explain the El existence of these divergent beliefs on the part of the respondents. First, it is possible that all combinations of strategies considered in this study were perceived by the respondents as being of equal merit, i.e. each one of the strategies might allow them to increase their dairy net income by about the same amount in the foreseeable future. Secondly, it is also possible that not all combinations of strategies over which they were questionned were perceived as being of equal merit but that the most economically justifiable ones might entail too great a loss in freedom to attract the revealed preferences of the majority of respondents. Thirdly, the regional dairy farmers may conceivably have developed a negative attitude towards all govern- mental programs in general. Such an attitude would imply that they tend to assign very high discount rates to new income opportunities 15A still wider spectrum of beliefs might be expected if the respondents were asked to formulate their preferences from a larger number of alternatives. 149 originating via further government's intervention.17 In the following chapters of this study WB shall attempt to analyse the economic consequences of each alternative set of strategies and determine whether any one of them might have a significantly higher payoff than others, at the farm level. We thus tentatively presume pm. that the first situation above is very unlikely to arise. .o . Summary . “.45. ‘J’fli'nu I.“ ‘ . .'§. z" . Three major means of increasing productive efficiency of regional .. .n dairy farming enterprises were described in this chapter. They were (10 improvements in herd stock, (2) varying feeding practices,and (3) farm consolidation and community pastures programs. Information obtained from a survey of regional dairy farms--representative of a limited segment of the total regional dairy farming industry-- was then used to determine whether or not the regional dairymen intend to expand herd sizes, improve feeding rates and/or increase the production capa- city of their cows, and if so how. Among the results, probably the most pertinent were the following: 1. Approximately 63 per cent of the respondents might be expected to further commit themselves to dairy farming in the foresee- able future. These respondents wished to increase 17While conceding that the Canadian dairy pricing policy has, in Lgeneral, been consistently favorable to fluid milk producers, it is appropriate to reemphasize the fact that, in recent years, about 25 per cent of manufacturing milk producers' gross income derived from the sale 6f milk consisted in subsidy payments. The amount of the subsidy is subject to revision each year, which is giving rise to some uncertainties among manufacturing milk producers. 150 the size and the milk yield of their dairy herds. These farmers might make a positive response to the government's proposed program despite the fact they held substantially different opinions concerning the most adequate stock replacement strategy to be followed. Approximately 60 per ‘r: cent of respondents indicating positive response tended to i: favoun raising their own replacement cows while the other 40 per cent might choose to buy some of or all ofctheir replace- IYF .-' l. .. . ._ . ment animals. The results of the survey also indicated that 4 ; articifial breeding might attract a large proportion of its potential users among those respondents who currently favour raising their own replacement cows. Approximately 34 per cent of all the respondents might be expected to hold back, at least temporarily, from further major inveStments in dairying. Some 60 per centvof these owned relatively small herds of 18 cows or less. Only 3 per cent of the population covered by this sample might be expected to leave dairy farming within the next five years. . As expected, the number of cows currently milked appeared to be associated with expansion intentions. No statistical relationship was found, however, between current herd size and the respondents‘ expressed intentions to improve their herds' milk yields. Moreover, no apparent statistical rela- tionship between current herd size and the respondents! 151 expressed preferences for an alternative stock replacement strategy was revealed by the survey results. 5. The current milk yields of the respondents' herds were found not to be statistically associated with either the likely decision to further expand herd's size or the respondents' expressed preferences for an alternative stock replacement. strategy. 1' [L.K.” The major conclusion which emerges at this juncture is that there is substantial disagreement among the respondents as to what is the most appropriate course of action for them to follow in order to improve their earnings while remaining committed to dairy farming. These results clearly indicate, in our opinion that there is a serious need for further investigation of the micro consequences that might be expected from alternative courses of action. CHAPTER VI MODEL AND DATA USED FOR SIMULATED EXPERIMENTS p9,. The main objective pursued in the following two chapters is to estimate the probable impact that alternative dairy development stra- tegies might have on the profitability of representative dairy farming enterprises in Eastern Quebec. To do so two dairy farming enterprises are simulated by use of a computer. This chapter describes the model, lays down all the assumptionsmade and specifies the levels of the variables used in the model. In the next chapter the findings are analysed and the most relevant implications are derived. On Simulation The technique used in this analysis is a simulation model. It is appropriate at this juncture to briefly describe the nature and the properties of the simulation technique. There is no consensus among the people who use the term simulation as to its exact meaning. Naylor pet als. define simulation somewhat narrowly as "numerical technique for conducting experiments on a digital computer, which involves certain types of mathematical and logical models that describe the behaviour of a business or economic system (or some 152 153 components thereof) over extended periods of real time."1 A much broader concept of simulation is presented by Shubik in whose opinion, "A simulation of a system or an organism is the operation of a model or simulator which is a representation of the system or organism."2 The definition that is used throughout this study is formulated as follows: "Computer simulation is a system analysis tool which uti- lizes subject matter theory, certain mathematical structures, program— ming logic and empirical analyses to condense a complex system into a mathematical formulation duplicating the essence of the real system.3 There appears to be a consensus, however, among research workers as to what is involved in setting up a simulation model. Simulation, as a tedhmiique: of analysis, involves setting up a model picturing the essence of a real situation and then performing experiments on the model. Each individual simulation run may be conceived as an experi- ment performed upon a model. A given experiment would thus involve operating a model after having specified the set of initial conditions, the set of values of the parameters used by formulating relations 1T.H. Naylor, J.L. Balintfy, D.S. Burdick, and Kong Chu, Computer Simulation Techniques, John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1966, p. 3. 2Martin Shdbik, "Simulation of the Industry and the Firm," American Economic Review, vol. L, no. 5, December, 1960, p. 909. 3Ml-L.Hayenga, T.J. Manetsch, and A.N. Halter, "Computer Simulation as a Planning Tool in Developing Economies," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. L, no. 5, December, 1968, p. 1755. 154 speCific to the model and finally the time paths of those variables treated as exogenous.4 Some of the major advantages of simulation over other research techniqus have been explored by Orcutt. He argues (1) that simulation techniques make possible the effective study of models containing “v large numbers of components, variables and relationships of almost any desired form, (2) that simulation techniques readily lend themselves to carrying out sensitivity analyses on the model considered, (3) that ‘P‘u-J’n8_I.J_‘i-. ' simulation techniques make it possible to carry out testing at various levels of aggregation and finally (4) that these techniques enable operating characteristics to be fitted to various sets of data by systematic trial-and-error procedures.S Another major advantage 0f simulation has been pointed out by G.L. Johnson. He argues that "mathematical simulation and system analysis offer an interdisciplinary 4Although it is beyond the scope of this study to go deeply into technical and methodological problems involved in using simula- tion it is appropriate to point out that there are several basic references available to those wishing to gain even a casual acquaint- anceship with the use of simulation. An uninitiated agricultural economist may find it convenient to refer to L.L. Manderschied, and G.L. Nelson, "A Framework for Viewing Simulation," Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. XVII, no. 1, February, 1969, pp. 33-41, and consult the references presented therein. An individual with advanced statistical knowledge may in turn find it convenient to read T.Y. Ling, Introduction to a Statistical Concept of Statics and Dynamics in Simulation Experiments, paper presented at the Symposium on the Design of Computer Simulation Experiments Held at Duke Univer- sity, October 14-16, 1968. 5G.L. Orcutt, "Simulation of Economic Systems," The American Economic Review, vol. L, no. 5, 1960, pp. 900-901. 155 approach for interrelating the different aspects of complex problems to see the consequences through time of alternative policies and programs (as reflected in different initial conditions and parameters)."6 Johnson also holds the opinion that simulation provides thernesearhh worker with a convenient way of getting around the intractable problem of reducing many objective functions to a single desirable outcome. The user of simulation is allowed to specify as many objective functions as he desires as long as they are logically linked to the factors and relationships conSidered in the model.7 E The early simulation studies led some researchers to believe that simulation in general and the results that it yields in particular generally lack the sharpness of focus obtained by other methods, such as linear programming. This argument, however, is debatable. Some people now condider linear programming one among many forms of simulation models. Recent simulation studies indicate that simulation does not necessarily lack sharpness of focus when the simulation model is designed correctly. The fact remains none the less that statisticians and econometricians tend to conclude that simulation models can produce relative results much more efficiently than absolute results. .Thus they argue that statistical 6G.L. Johnson, Relevant Rural Development Research for West Africa, paper presented at a Seminar on Research on an Agricultural Develommaliin East and West Africa, Michigan State University, June 9-14, 1968, pp. 25-26. 7Other advantages of simulation techniques are described by R. Suttor, and R.J. Grom, "Computer Models and Simulation," Journal of Farm Economics, vol. 46, no. 5, December, 1964, p. 1342. 156 inference drawn from simulation is mostly useful for a conditional, comparative and relative prediction.8 In general,runm:methodological discussions concerning simulation boil down to the crucial issue of how one should go about validating his results. The usual procedure is to deaign a model, specify the 7 f1 variables, the relationshipsand the parameters and have the computer program simulate a situation which is familiar to the researcher, who can then compare the results with his prior knowledge.9 Another proce- dure which is now being developed advocates thorough investigation of g the statistical properties of probabilistic simulation models. Research in "simulation statistics" just started in recent years, which partly explains why it is not yet commonly used. The apparent reluctance on the part of simulation users towards elaborate statistical validation is thus understandable since the proponents of the statistical validation approach have yet to develop statistical tests readily applicable to simulation models. Therefore, the former validation approach will be used in this study. Description of the Model The model used in this analysis has five major components (Figure 6). These are (l) the unit of analysis constituting the core component 8See T.Y. Ling, op. cit., pp. 16-17, for a discussion of the con- cept of simulation inference and its applicability. It is interesting to note that some authors have attempted to dispel this criticism by arguing that simulation is not aimed at long-run predictions and that the objec- tive of a long-run simulation study it'not forecasting but rather design- ing strategy for an unpredictable future. See E.P. Holland, and R.W. Gillespie, Experimentsgon a Simulated Underdeveloped Economy, Cambridge, Mass., The MIT Press, 1963, p. 209. 9L.V. Manderschied and G.L. Nelson, op. cit., pp. 34-35. 157 mawnmcoflumfimm Emumhm .o cuswwm .muwvwmnnm xaae MGHMSuommscmE Hanovow can Hmwocfi>oumu ”muonpoun muwmv .onwm who: a“ mommouo as“ new mucmam>ounaw Mom mucoEcuwsvmu Hmanmo a“ newsman: “common poumfinsgm mac uo>o aon ammo pmucsoumav mo osHm> ucomoumn mama» Hum 300 you now nuuspoum xHaE omnum>oumu mHDmZH wAm voxwz ”muoauuaua unmaowmcws umSan ”mouwuomua unmeoomanuu xooum kuwmcu ”moowuomua wawwocmu azmzomzoo mace Aav ezmzzomH>zm . ANV oHanHouucoo macum>wum mmEmumoua aofimamuxcn mmsmuwonn wcwcfimuu HmHSuHsoHuwMu mhuwaoa uwvouo Hausuanuwummu ”Bmuwoua chaumma hues:EEOUu mamumoun coaumpAHOmcoo Sham: oHanHouunoo hacfifinsm mHszH mqmop pudendum mum mononuconmm aw womoaoco apogee: snap .s wanna xfivcomm< .m xwvcomn< aw venom on can week some new moeoouso neoconoumm on OH sN ma mm mN mama ms nu wH NH ma wH moms. . . onus who: I I wBOU MO thEDC I I Amway Aaoev afiANV AsmHv Assay Amev NNe.a Neu.q Hoo.a Noo.o nmo.o smN.o mama Aowv AHNV Assav ANomV ,NOHV Asmmv NH~.Q Hmn.o mam.m mew.m NNH.© «ah.m seas . . .nnmms tea coHuuscoum I I xHHE mo moaned I I mwmum>< Assay Aowv Aoowv AmNNV AoNNV AHmHV awo.m cam new.m caa.fi mom.~ osm.H mass AHmHV Aumv Assoc AsoHV AmoHV Aomfiv smm.H HNN.H wes.~ one Hmm.a woo.~ moms . . .numms use oEoocH I I mumHHoc I I seen umz o m a m N H ponEn: ucoefluoaxm owmafim moumu omeHm moons ImmeHw moons 0:.mmump wcwcomw on .wcwpoo wGfiUoOM oc.wcwpuum wcwcwvw MEHUUQW UCUHHDU UmwwthCH uCflHHDU UQmNUHUCH UCQHMDU “NOW meOUUSO pommwuuaH fibwumcHEwmcH Hmwuwmuy%<. mow>H0m Hohsumz woumfiwumm wmmson mucoeoomfimmu HH< Show :30 co pomamu mucoEoomHmop HH< mucoEHnmaxm pwumFDva m.man can moma .nmfiwmumuum EmquMm o>wumcpoufi< pecan H Eumm How onoouao wouuonoum .o¢ mqmoo oumvcmum one mononucoumm aw oomofiuco mucosa: onHa .m manna xwocommd .m xfiocoom< ca o=50m on fine now» some now onouuso wouowmonmm mm on an an am am mm on mm mama mN mN mm mN ma mN mm mm mm some. . swam who: Amzoo mo umnEDcv feauv Amva Amsuv AHHHV lasso AmHHV Acouv Ammwv Amway oo3.w oom.w aoH.w ase.m awe.m use.e ass.“ ems.“ oam.k mama ANOV flame Anev Amsv Awov AmaV Achy x-Hv Asmav soa.o osw.e mom.s «Na.o mmo.e smw.o Naa.o «Nw.o maa.o memo. . .esou has cofluosooue Aafifla mo mocsoav mwmuo>< AeNmV AsomV Amomv Aomflv Amamv Assay Aaaev Amamv Aman ONH.m mam.s eco.s coo.m oHa.s o~s,m wqa.e omo.s smo.m mmafi AmoHv AonV AHOHV Asmfiv Amuse Amway AmoHV ANNHV AwNHV awe.m H¢H.N Noo.H mwo.m mma,m wmo.s msm.N som.~ sea.~ moms . . . .ptmm» use mecca“ AmpmHHoov meu umz ma «H ma NH as as a m a .wpesc seesanuaxm ommfifiw mwmafim moump mmmfiflm wmeHm woumu owmfifim ommHHm wmumu poor weeoouso on cows mewomow 0: Low3 meweoow o: tuwz woweoow ecumefiumm ucwuuso mowowom wammuUCH ucmuuso wcfioomm omwmmpocH uceuuso wcfioomm oommmuocH coHumaEomcfl Hmflowwwup< ouw>uom Hmudumz urwsoa mucmawomHawu HH< Show E30 :0 oomwmw mucwEoomHamp HH< m mnma one oomfi .mofiwoumuum Emumoum m>wumcuou~< noon: HH Show you onoouso wouoomoum .nq mqmjn APPENDIX B 256 FACTORS AFFECTING YIELDS OF DAIRY COWS Suppose that the level of production of a cow in a given period to can be expressed as the dependent variable in the following functional relationship: Qto ' f (Qto , Qto_1 , Cto where, 9 Cto-j’ Ito a EtO 2 Bk : Bm ) Qto - production (lbs. of milk) of a cow in period to; qt - quantity of feed fed to the cow in period to; Ct:_j - composition of rations fed in periods to-j; where j a l, 2, ....., r and to-j>’03 Ito - index of inherited factors of the cow identifiable in period t0 Eto g index of environmental factors affecting the production of the cow at time to; Bk - breed of cow, where k = 1, 2, ---,P; Bm - breeding practice followed, where m a l, 2,...,s. This functional relationship states that the production of a cow during a period to may depend upon (1) the quantity and the composition of rations fed during period to, (2) the quantity and the composition of rations fed in periods preceding to, (3) the inheritance factors peculiar to the type of cow, (4) the environmental factors (weather, housing and milking arrangements, handling of cow by farmer, number of milking daily, and other factors) believed to affect the yields of cows, (5) the breed of cows considered, and (6) the breeding practices followed. Since neither the functional form nor the parameters of this relationship can be specified because of absence of data on most of these variables, we propose an alternative method for comparing the production capacity of dairy cows in Eastern Quebec with that of dairy The effects of the levels of feeding (qto and of the composition of rations (Ct ) can be neutralized -- at 2 partially -- by choosing a period to guch that qt cows in other parts of Canada. leas significantly diverge from region to region. Canadian Census of Agriculture data allow one to compare the daily milk production per cow (as of July lrst of that year) on a countywise basis. Since most cows in Quebec and Ontario are on pasture at that time of the year, it might reasonably expected that feed ration levels and composition do not diverge too much from cow to cow, from farm to farm, and from region to region. To the extent that this presumption is valid, Appendix'rable 1 indicates that dairy cows in Eastern Quebec are relatively less productive than those found in other regions of Quebec, which in turn appear to be relatively less productive than those found in Ontario. and to-i) 0; 8 quantity of feed fed to the cow in periods to-i’ Where1II, 2, 00.0.,n Ct - composition of the ration fed in period to; and Cto do not For instagce, the 1966 3 257 Assuming that the influence of qt and Ct are neutralized by this method of comparison, low levels of coas'yielgs in Eastern Quebec would have to be attributed to some of or all of the following causes; predominance of low producing dairy breeds, poor management practices and/or difficult environment for dairying. Unfortunately, the importance of these factors cannot be isolated due to the absence of data. It appears safe to conclude that a typical dairy farmer in Eastern Quebec milks cows of lower production capacity than the average dairyman in Quebec and Ontario, while recognizing that our estimates of these differences may not be particularly accurate. The major bias involved in using this method has to do with the differences in quality of roughage from farm to farm and from region to region. The production capacity of . Easteanuebec dairyicows might be significantly underestimated in Appendix Table 1 if it happened that they are fed rather low quality roughage in comparison to other regions. APPENDIX TABLE 1. Daily Production per Cow in Quebec, Ontario and by County of Eastern Quebec, July lrst, 1966. Daily production Area per cow (pounds of milk) a) Counties of Eastern Quebec Bonaventure 27.17 Gaspe-East 26.01 Gaspe-West 27.47 Matane 24.04 Matapédia 26.96 Rimouski 26.70 Riviére-du-Loup 26.90 Témiscouata 26.78 b) Province of Quebec All counties 30.55 c) Province of Ontario All counties 35.53 Source: 1966 Census of Agriculture, Ottawa, Canada, Catalogue no. 96-606. 4. 258 APPENDIX C QUESTIONNAIRE NUMERO , NOM Combien de vaches trayez-vous actuellement? No. De quelle race(s) sont ces vaches? (1) Jersey; No. (2) Ayrshire; No. (3) Guernsay; No. (4) Autres; No. (5) Spécifiez la race: Considérant chacune de vos vaches individuellement, pourriez-vous indiquer combien de ces vaches sont dans les classes d'age suivantes et combien de livres de lait ces vaches ont produites approximati- vement au cours de l'année 1968? Nombre de vaches dans Production annuelle Classe d'age cheque classe d'age (19681de ces vaches 2 a 4 ans (1) (5) 5 a 7 ans (2) (6) 8 a 10 ans (3) (7) 10 ans et plus (4) (8) Durant combien de jours ou de mois par année trayez-vous ces vaches en moyenne? (1) jours on (2) mois Quel est ordinairement 1e pourcentage de gras dans le lait que ces vaches produisent? % Quel est le poids de vos vaches qui ont entre 6 et 8 ans? lbs. Combien aviez-vous de vaches dans votre troupeau il y a un an? No. Au cours de l'année derniére, avez-vous vendu des vaches que vous ne vouliez plus traire parce qu'elles ne produisaient pas assez de lait? (1) oui ~ (2) non Si oui, pourriez-vous indiquer 1e poids approximatif de ces vaches que vous avez vendues ainsi que leur age et le prix “net que vous avez regu pour chacune d'elles? Vache no. Age Poids Prix I-l-‘th-I IA‘IIII. I'll-El I Jill: II‘ 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 259 Au cours de l'année derniére, avez-vous vendu des génisses que vous avez élevées? (l) oui (2) non si oui, pourriez-vous indiquer 1e poids approximatif de ces génisses, ainsi que leur age et la prix net que vous avez regu pour chacune d'elles? Génisse No. Age Poids Prix 1 2 ______ _____ ______ 3 ______ ______ ______ 4 _____ ._____ _____ 5 Avez-vous vendu des jeunes veaux (moins de 2 semaines) au cours de 1'année derniére? (1) oui (2) non si oui, a quel prix avez-vous vendu ces jeunes veaux?(3) $ Combien de vos vaches ont donné naissance a un veau vivant 1'année derniére? (1) No. de (2) au total Avez-vous l'intention d'augmenter la taille de votre troupeau laitier au cours des 5 prochaines années? (1) oui (2) non 31 non, qu'allez-vous faire? (3) traire le meme nombre de vaches (4) vendre votre ferme . . . . . . (5) réduire le nombre de vaches si oui, combien de vaches par année croyez-vous étre capable d'ajouter a votre troupeau au cours des 5 prochaines années? (6) No. (Si la réponse est non a la question 12, passez immédiatement a la question 15). Si vous avez l'intention d'augmenter 1a taille de votre troupeau laitier, de quelle fagon entendez-vous procéder? (1) Elever toutes vos nouvelles vaches vous-méme? (2) Acheter toutes vos nouvelles vaches? (3) Elever et acheter vos nouvelles vaches? Si vous avez l'intention d'acheter toutes ou seulement quelques-unes de vos nouvelles vaches au cours des 5 prochaines années, combien en achéteriez-vous si ces vaches produisaient 8,000 livres de lait et se vendaient aux prix suivants? (1) $250 (2) $200 (3) $100 Combien devriez-vous payer actuellement si vous vouliez acheter une tonne de foin dans votre localité? $ par tonne II. l'..ll II 11 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 260 Combien devriez-vous payer actuellement pour louer un acre de paturage dans votre localité? $ par acre Considérant chacun des items suivants, pourriezavous indiquer combien vous en avez présentement ainsi que leur valeur approximative? (1) (3) (5) (7) (9) (11) (13) (15) (17) (19) (21) (23) (25) (27) Quel type d'étable avez-vous présentement? Items acres en paturage; acres en foin; acres en mais; tracteur(s); trayeuse(s) électrique (s); séparateur (s); charrue(s) a tracteur; semoir(s); batteuse(s); lieuse(s); étable (s) avec équipement; camionnette(s) et camion(s); silo(s); sécheuse(s) a foin; 221211; (2) __ (4) __ (6) __ (8) __ (10) (12) (14) __ (16)______ (18) (20) (22) (24) (26) (28) (1) étab1e(s) avec stalles; (2) étab1e(s) sans stalles; Si vous songiez a augmenter 1a taille de votre troupeau de 10 vaches (10 vaches de plus) au cours des 5 prochaines années, combien de capital pensez-vous que vous devriez investir sur votre ferme, excluant 1e coat des vaches? Combien de tonnes de foin par acre récoltez-vous sur votre ferme au cours d'une année normale? tonnes Combien de coupes de foin obtenez=vous sur votre ferme au cours d°une année normale? coupes Quel est le cofit moyen ou 1e prix (si vous 1'achetez) d'une tonne de moulées concentrées avec lesquelles vous nourrissez vos vaches? par tonne Durant combien d'années devez-vous observer 1e niveau de production de lait d'une vache avant de décider de garder sa génisse pour la production de lait? ’années Parmi les critéres suivants, 1equel utilisez-vous le plus souvent pour décider de garder une génisse produite par une de vos vaches? (1) 1a vache qui a eu cette génisse donne au moins 300 livres de lait de plus que vos autres vaches, par année (2) la vache ayant cette génisse donne un peu plus de lait (entre 0 et 300 livres de p1us)que vos autres vaches (3) 1a vache ayant cette génisse donne a peu prés 1a meme quantité de lait que vos autres bonnes vaches 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. 261 Jusqu'a quel age devez-vous garder une vache avant de vous faire une opinion definitive sur sa qualité? années Avez-vous un ou des boeuf(s)(ou taureau) que vous utilisez pour la reproduction? (l) oui (2) non si oui, étez-vous satisfait de la qualité de ce ou ces boeufs que vous utilisez pour la reproduction? (3) oui (4) non Si vous n'avez pas vos ou votre propre(s) boeuf(s) pour la repro- duction, louez-vous les services d'un boeuf appartenant a quel- qu'un d'autre? (1) oui (2) non si oui, combien devez-vous payer a chaque fois que vous en louez un? (3) $ Avez-vous l'intention d'améliorer la qualité de votre troupeau laitier durant les 5 prochaines années? (l) oui (2) non si oui, lesquelles des méthodes suivantes avez-vous l'intention d'employer? (3) améliorer la qualité des boeufs de reproduction; (4) donner seulement plus de foin; (5) donner seulement plus de moulées concentrées; (6) donner plus de foin et de moulées; (7) acheter des génisses de meilleure qualité; (8) produire vous-meme des génisses de meilleure qualité; Avez-vous déja eu recours a l'insémination artificielle pour fertiliser vos vaches dans le passé? (1) oui (2) non si oui, combien vous en a-t-il cofité par vache? (3) $ Si l'insémination cofitait moins cher, seriez-vous prét a utiliser cette méthode pour améliorer la qualité de votre troupeau? (1) 0U1.________ (2) non _________ si oui, quel prix seriez-vous prét a payer par vache fertilisée? (3) $ Combien de livres de lait pensez-vous que vos propres génisses donneront a leur maturité (7 a 10 ans)? Par exemple, si vous considérez 10 de vos génisses, combien d'entre elles, a votre avis, pourraient se situer dans les classes suivantes de pro- duction annuelle? (l) moins de 5,000 livres de lait (2) 5,000 a 5,999 " (3) 6,000 a 6,999 " (4) 7,000 a 7,999 " (5) 8,000 a 8,999 " (6) 9,000 a 9,999 " (7) 10,000 et plus " 32. 33. 34. 35. 262 Quel prix recevez-vous présentement pour la vente de 100 livres de lait? $ Combien devez-vous payer présentement dans votre localité pour acheter une génisse qui porte son premier veau? Combien de vaches avez-vous retirées de votre troupeau l'année derniére pour les raisons suivantes? (l) maladie (2) mortalité (3) ne produit pas assez (4) autres raisons Pourriez-vous indiquer, approximativement, combien des aliments suivants tout votre troupeau laitier a consommés au cours de l'année derniére? (1) foin: tonnes (2) paturage: nombre de vaches par acre; (3) ensilage; tonnes; (4) moulées concentrées; tonnes. 263 APPENDIX D SUMMARY OF SURVEY RESULTS ON FEEDING RATES APPENDIX TABLE 2. Annual Forage and Grain Fed, and Milk Production per Cow: Dairy Herds of Mixed Breeds, Eastern Quebec, 1969-8 Quantity Number Forage fedE Milk production per cow of grains of farms Standard Standard. fed in group Mean deviation Mean deviation (pounds) (tons) (tons) (pounds) (pounds) 0 -1,499 19 6.0e 1.45 6.130 710 1,500-1,999 15 6.3e 0.87 6.340 920 2,000-2,499 19 6.56 0.79 6.540 830 2,500 or more 15 6.7e 0.86 6.630 1,040 Source: Eastern Quebec Dairy Farms Survey, 1969. aThese estimates were obtained through the following steps. First, the quantities of hay and grain mixtures the respondents reported to have fed their dairy herds in 1968 were divided by the number of dairy cows in their herds at the end of that year. This computation was carried out only for dairy farms reporting mixed-bred herds of 10 cows or more (68 respondents). The estimated quantifies of grains fed per farm pa:cow were then used to classify the respondents in the grain categories specified in the left hand-side column of the above table. Second, the quantities of hay apparently fed per cow per farm were added up for all farms classified in a specific grain feeding rate category and divided by the number of farms in this category. The result might be conveniently labelled the mean quantity of hay fed annually. In this step, each mean quantity of hay fed annually was increased by 1.8 tons of pasture per cow to obtain the mean quantities of forage fed which appear in the table above. In other words, it was assumed that all cows in each respondent's herd have access to the equivalent of one acre of pasture-land yielding about 1.8 tons of eatable forage per acre. It was also assumed that the respondents do not harvest significant quantities of oats as silage. The same steps were followed to compute the quantities of milk produced per cow in 1968. bThe composition of grain mixtures reported by the respondents does not differ much from farm to farm. The mixtures are largely based on locally grown oats fed as grains. CIt is common knowledge among dairy scientists that the quality and/or 264 palatibility of forage fed determine, to a significant extent, the percentage of a forage ration that a cow will effectively consume. With the exception of alfalfa which is sporadically grown in Eastern Quebec (Alfalfa and alfalfa mixtures accounted for less than 5 per cent of the total regional cropland devoted to the production of hay in the region in 1966), it appears that the types of hay grown in the region range from poor hay (relatively small proportion of legumes) to medium quality hay rather than from medium-quality hay to excellent hay (large proportion of legumes harvested at an early bloom stage). For several reasons, it was not possible to obtain accurate estimates of the percentage of forage rations fed which are effectively consumed by these herds. Crude estimates obtained by multiplying the mean quantities of forage fed annually per farm per cow (third column of table) by .9 might come close to describe actual forage feeding rates. dThe relatively high standard deviations of these estimates clearly indicate that there are substantial variations in feeding rates and milk yields from farm to farm. eThe fact that both the grain feeding and the forage feeding rates are shown to increase simultaneously does not imply that these estimates are inconsistent. Apparently, two factors have contributed to this rather unorthodox result. First, it was found that the lowest grain-fed category (O-l,499) includes a large proportion of respondents with small herds and/or with no apparent interests in further investing in dairying whereas the uppermost grain-fed category (2,500 or more) mostly included respondents with relatively large herds and/or with expressed interests in further committing themselves to dairying. Second, farmers with low dairy feeding rates tended to raise more animal units (other than dairy cows) per dairy cow than dairy farmers with high feeding rates. Infill .N'J'vt. t. 1 265 Inf/u ~ .. 4.- - I - - - - I I ma - I I - I ma ACOU\mV ”>6: mo umoo .m - - - I - - - - omo.H - I - I - cmo.~ Acmm;\mecsoav ”who: msu CH m30o menace mo DLuHmBpron wwwum>< .N I I I I I I I I com I I I I I 0mm Apmm>\m>mp wo umnEscv ":oHumuomH mo cuwcmfi mwapo>< .m 0mm 0mm omN 0mm 0mm Aommz\mv vmmucmeomHemu Ummmcopsa mo umoo .m I - - - I - I I mes - I - - - I moi Anmm;\mv ommucoEmomHamu wcfimflm» mo umou .d I I I I I I I I N I I I I I N Aumm>\m30o we amnescv mo>wuommno LDBOuw mafia who: .m ---s -----m 88.8 nnmuwm who: CH mommuocfi uo\ccm ucmEm>ouaEH pom mHLmem>m Hmufiamo mo ucsoe< .N I I I I I I I I mm I I I I I wH Am30o mo ponsscv adobe: HmfiuHcH cw m3oo mewxfiwe wo monsoz .4 MH «H mH NH HH 0H o m m o m c m N H I oEmc manmwum> mucmeumaxm pmumHDEwm ”HH Show ucmEgumaxm pwumHDEHm ”H Eumm P mucmeHumexm emumH55am cu mmfinmapm> on emcwamm< mmsfim> .m mam 2H Qmm: mm “ouHm wo xovcH zuHHmso Acou\wV smoumuucooaou mo umoo owmuo>< Aunwaos emu we so ”mumuucoocoo :H Mouume hut mo N Auanos pow mo NV "oumuucoocoo mo mHmmHmcm zap wmucon>HavoImm£ mo :Ou pom ow6u0m woumo>hmn mo osHm> Auewfioz now do so mowmuow :H nouume hue N Huewams use no NV ”emu mommuow COEEoo mo mmeHmcm zne Aucoo Homv ousummm we now zap owmuom no N Amvcsoav wmxmn you usto3 huon mo weapon ooH non Houume hub wo mvcsom ”coHumu wchoom HmuOH Amww\mvasomv omuanma anon mo weapon ooH use owmuow mo oxmucH umoHHmam .oN .wH .5H .0H .mH .qH .MH .NH .HH .oH mH «H mH NH HH 0H m w o m o m N mucoEHuoaxw voumH58Hm “HH Emma mucosduomxm woumHDEHm “H spam mama oHanum> AconcauaouV m anzmmm< 267 mm mm ooN ooN mm Om ooN om Om on on m5 m5 5m Om 0N.¢H mmH mH mm ooN mm OON om on on m5 m5 5m 0m oN.¢ mMH mH ANV omHmuHamo mo umoo qucsupomao HNV cmu0uomw mucoumwmua umem: ARV Em.Haou now wm>mm WHmu cucumn :oHuozpouQ mwmpo>m new: «0 N Annamav mucoEmomHmou now vo>mm umuswnmo mucumn cum: cH mummy ANV Munoz Loom wcH>Hmo m3oo mo N HmmucmEmomHmou new boom wchoHoxm .3oo poo mumoo ammo A.Dso \mv mxHHE pom vw>Hooon moHum uoz Aemos\mv ”monouou COHuosvoua 30H mo mmsmomn ooHHao m3ou mo maHm> Aemu;.mv . “mo>Hmo wHo x663 osu coco mmoH mo maHm> Apmm>\xHHE mo mpcnoav xmmMMMHms .H.< mo quommmo coHuuapoum :H unmouocH wouooaxm .om .mN .wN .5N .oN .mN .qN .mN .NN .HN MH NH HH OH 0 mH qH mucmEHuwmxm woumHDEHm ”HH Eumm ”III . mwcdawmomxm wmumHSEwwI II]: o n q n ‘l'l II 'II II.I|I‘4l AconcaucouV m xHQmem< mew: mHanum> 268 uH umsu ANV .ccm AHq mHnmev mmcmu NuHHmsc comm 30H onu CH NHucmuuso mH H Show umLu AHV possmmm mH un .poesmmHw coHuocaH NuHmcoo NuHHHnmnoua onu ou wchuooom uocHEuouop NHEOpcmu mH NuHowamo :oHuospoua vmuomaxo uHoLH .w:H>Hmo umun uHocu ou uoHum pmmmzouam on ou possmoum who Sosa mo HH< .mEhdu wchHmu xUOum NuHmo uoNHHmHomam Eouw uzwaon possmmm mucoEoomHamu HH

umm wchomun mo umoo oanocH uoc moooo .uoasmmHavoIousumEv aoHuuavoua paw Hosea: coHumuome .ponovacoo Show umHaoHuuma map How menu pmumHDEHm uosuo cH HH Show how 5 can cH can H Euwm H@.Hcsu :H uom mH oHanum> ecu nona um m=Hm> onu uQSu moumoHc5H I "Honexm .mm>u:m maumm NuHma uonoso cuoummm scum mum .vawHomam mmH3uocuo mmoHc: .mcoHumoHuHoon mo moousom "mounom I I I I I m I I I I I m U AcoHuMuomH mo “mafiacv I mauHommmo COHuosvoum .msoa oumon>m L Ou poems: coHumDomH mo nonesz .mm I I I I I I I I S I I I I I S _ at _ cmwchhHmp CH woumo>cHou M on 0» ckumE mmouw Ho N .Nm -------o -----o 28:3 ammEoocH Ho HmSmupnuHS Hmscc¢ .Hm 2 S 29.-me S S a m m- o m w. m N H m 052.. mum-Ill mwmmawmuoxm pmumHSEHm "HH Spam BcoEHhmaxo woumHneHm ”H Show - Hp H > I s!-!. III:;III-II;II ,IIIIILIIIII-- -I ll Ill. Q. llll llIlllll l Ill! Illll lIII :lIlI'l-llllll ll! Ill l-ll-lu Illl Ill I .l-Il Ill l I. I I. .I Il-l- I Alli-I I: V NewscHucoov m xHozmmm< 269 .mH van «H .mH .o .m aucoaHuoaxo now 300 use muuoo ooH>uum wchooun novsHocHH .AcmH .m mouv beeswax xHHE Ho weapon ocN o>Hum>uoucoox .«wH swam co ponHuumoc coHuucaw cOHuanuumHv Ho u=Hm> vouomaxmn .uEhmm wchku xUOun munv voNHHmHoomm can no vomumu uzoo mo Aucon>H9voIouaumav NuHomeo :oHuosvoum vouoomxo o£u ou stva uom uH uH .uaau coHumHnBHn nonuo HHu aH .mucuvcoamop uzu an vouuomuu 300 you coHuonpoum xHHa mo Ho>uH Huaccu onu um uum nH mouHm mo novaH muHHmsv any .a van a .5 .N .H menu :OHumHaaHu GHH .vuon muHmp «nu ovum ou cocoa: nH cumuw uuao Ho ucaoaw uo>oum£3 aHnasm nouHumuouco mono :36 o.uoeumu «nu uwnu cOHuaaauuu can have: voustaHn who many HHuHHoa 63 .aonou osu :H ucme>HavoI>a£ mo aou a mo magma aH NHmHSDnu ouuou omuHHo nuuo no so» a .cowon mag aH omeHu uuwo Ho sou 6 Ho uwcu mm 5038 no ouHsu u50pm mH has no sou a no 299 0:» moawm .aonou onu cu Auaou m.5 \m¢wv ow usonm ma :Hmum uumo cH meow0u0m oeoocH no menu» aH omeHu uuao mo sou a mo o=Hm> may .anuw no cwnu nonumu omeHu no vuuao>hmn mum has» :05: uuuo pow powwouucH on coo 299 HO :oHuoavoua umnu uuom osu uooHHou ou povcuunu 6H mash .mH was NH.o menu aoHumHsauu :H 30H oH ucon>HavoIhmn mo so» you owmuom wouuo>uos mo oaHu>m .H¢ qumH :H vouconoua one moumu wchoom «soaum> can you chHuoonHoomm .AmH can NH .o «can aOHuaHsawmv owcwu.5uHHm=u comm :HaoHuusuomhsz osu ou no a¢H can HH.m menu coHustaHmv omeHn uaonuwa oumu wchoom ans on» honuHo ou uanm coo on uwSu can owcmu wcHooom Esavoa oSu :H NHuauuuau mH HH anon mo uoumuono on» uwnu avenues onHw uH Ac use ¢.N mash coHumHssHav omeHm uaosuHB ouwu wchoom :st on» On amuse coo 835203 a fig: 270 me la.- . I. .a: «wow oEoocH oHQMmomch NHHewm kuouoo omHumuuuco huamp ecu mo COHuanuucoo onu mm momaomxo hHHEmH :H mommouocH pom mBoHHm ouommuoau coHumonHuoam mHna .umom comm mcquHmp :H ucmEumo>aHou you oHanHm>w mH mmHuauouco muHmv m£u_5n vacuum ckumE mmopw one «o ucoo you oH umnu voasmmm mH uH .hcaum was» 6H .oEoocH HoopHmou 0:» Ho moumsm uHonu no“ wcwuomeoo mm um3oH> mum mvcsm muaofiummgflH pom momma momHueuouam huHmv use momcmmxm NHHEmma .zosum mHau :H Hmavaou m on wouwopu mH momcoaxo NHHemw pom oEooaH Ho Hmswuccuw3 Hmsccow ShouImcoH co mwchumo Ho mummo .vum: mnu cH NomoHHm m3oo can» o>Hu09poum ouoE NHnmnoum «H m3oo ousume Ho aoHuoscoua ucmuuso «so «0 once you m5 coca whoa monsooum umcu uoHHos a many .umHHo: w you nouumm conuo>coo own vumwcmum onu mH mHskc .meumm vo>o>unm on» no umos so wouuomou mm3 50H53 umnu amsu ucowGHuum mmoH NHuanHm mH coHumonHoomm mHne .uaoeoomeou a Mom HHwo no: mcH>mm nochcoo ustE weapon 0:» muomon AmHmmn ucuHm>HsuoIousumEv coHuoavoua ammuo>m who: Ho uaoo you m5 unmoH um Samoa owns 300 w umnu moHHHoomm mHanum> mHnae NewsaaucouV m xHozmmma 271 APPENDIX F SUMMARY OF PROJECTED OUTCOMES FOR FARMS I AND II APPENDIX TABLE 4. Projected Outcomes for Farm I Under Alternative Program Strategies Simulated Experimentsa Estimated Outcomes Year 2 3 l 4 5 6 -- (dollars) Net cash income per year 1969 1,391 976 1,448 1,271 1,534 1970 1,672 1,005 1,728 1,345 1,570 1971 1,854 1,197 2,043 1,273 1,856 1972 2,100 1,409 2,469 1,209 2,230 1973 2,207 1,599 2,955 1,069 2,430 1974 2,347 1,672 3,326 966 2,809 1975 2,563 1,970 3,848 846 3,087 Average -- (pounds of milk) production per cow per year 1969 6,122 5,845 5,978 6,331 6,212 1970 6,261 5,991 6,190 6,407 6,597 1971 6,355 6,187 6,494 6,425 6,804 1972 6,502 6,289 6,885 6,082 6,996 1973 6,466 6,363 7,202 5,660 7,191 1974 6,536 6,435 7,390 5,267 7,332 1975 6,627 6,602 7,691 4,267 7,422 -- (number of cows in herd) -- Herd size 1969 18 17 18 15 18 1970 20 19 20 14 20 1971 22 21 22 13 22 1972 23 23 24 12 24 1973 24 24 25 11 26 1974 26 26 27 11 28 1975 28 28 29 10 30 aSee p. 193 foradescription of practices identifying experiments. bl 443' 01‘ "Al'. I! 272 ll“ mm on em Rm Rm Rm mm on mRoH «m an em mm. mm mm em em «RoH mm mm mm mm mm mm mm mm mRaH Hm Hm Hm Hm Hm Hm on Hm RRoH on mm am am RN om oN om HRoH RN RR RR RN RR RR RN RR oRmH mm mm mm mm mm mm mm mm momH INHI spam II AmBOU mo honescv II ooH.m mom.m moH.m Roo.w Rwo.w Hse.R mHe.R oas.R mRaH Nmm.R «so.» new.R ems.» swe.m HNm.R NOR.R Hm~.R «RmH woo-R oeR.R Roo.R mmH.w moH.w meN.R me.R cm~.R MRaH Roq.R Raq.R ces.R oww.R sow.R RaH.R RoH.R omH.R RRoH me~.R wR~.R mm~.R oRm.R Hmm.R wHH.R moo.R omo.R HRaH Rmo.R mmo.R Rmo.R owH.R on.R moo.o cum.o oHo.o oRoH 00R.o osw.o mow.o mmw.o mmm.o onw.o NRR.o -m.o somH 300 was II AxHHE Ho mvcsoav II aoHuosvoum ommuo>< ONH.m mmm.¢ moo.e om0.m oHa.s o~e.m wsR.¢ owo.q mRmH Hmw.e oHH.q wRo.m NoH.m mus.q mmH.m RRm.e osoIm «RoH wmo.e oRo.m wmm.m omo.s oqm.m mma.~ owo.q mR¢.m mRoH mRm.m mo~.m Rmm.~ mmo.e oRm.m Hum.~ omw.m Re~.m NRaH oun.m RRm.~ ~oo.~ moo.m mom.~ m~m.~ -m.m mmo.~ HRoH wNH.m Rmm.~ oom.~ mmH.m sem.~ omm.~ mm~.m smo.~ oRaH Hwo.~ HoH.~ Hom.H mmo.~ me.N mam.H mem.~ «on.a momH “was “In «EooaH ammo uoz I . HmumHHoev .- mH «H L «H M NH HH 0H m m “was musoouso _ . umumEHumm _ H I 5 .mmeoumuum Emuwoum m>HumcuouH< nova: HH Show you mmeoouso wouomnoum .m mHm