MSU RETURNING MATERIAL“: PEace in book drop to LIBRAIUES remove this checkout from ‘3“ your record. E3353 W111 be charged if hoof—1's returned after the date stamped be10w. .‘—. Mm..." u—uno—‘u— al-au-u———-— PUBLIC POLICY AND THE DURATION OF PUBLIC EMPLOYEE STRIKE ACTIVITY By Robert Charles Rodgers A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Labor and Industrial Relations School 1981 ABSTRACT PUBLIC POLICY AND THE DURATION OF PUBLIC EMPLOYEE STRIKE ACTIVITY by Robert C. Rodgers Long strikes by public employees arouse public concern because of a potential threat to the health and safety of a community. High political (and possibly economic) costs accrue to employers when essential services are interrupted. Costs also are incurred by workers as a result of foregone income. The determinants of the duration of all nonrecognition strikes occurring in local government bargaining units in the United States between January, 1977 and October, 1978 were thus examined in this study. Factors expected to affect strike duration included economic considerations (the expectations of the union membership and the economic constraints on the public employer's ability to make concessions) as well as noneconomic considerations (bargaining unit structures and the local labor relations environment). In addition, the impact on duration of various impasse resolution mechanisms were Robert C. Rodgers ABSTRACT: Public Policy and the Duration of Public Employee Strike Activity examined. Results for the impasse resolution factors, controlling for other relevant considerations in a regression, indicated that states with compulsory mediation provisions tended to have slightly shorter strikes. Mandatory penalty requirements were not, however, related to duration. An injunction reduced the length of strikes in the smaller bargaining units, but in the larger units, this effect was reversed. An unexpected and also inconclusive result was a positive association between mediation and strike duration. Results for other determinants indicated that strikes were longer when (l) the labor costs of the striking bargaining unit were a large component of total labor costs, (2) the union supported the strike, (3) the issue concerned economic matters, and (4) noneducational personnel were involved. Oct .nu .fiu b. v «A ~ I ~. . I“. ACKNOWLE DGMENTS This study benefited greatly from the many comments and suggestions from Professors Richard Block, Jack Stieber and Cheryl MarantO‘ from the School of Labor and Industrial Relations, Jack Hunter from the Psychology department, and Terry Moe from the Political Science department. I am deeply indebted to each of these individuals for their many hours of thoughtful review and evaluation of many drafts of this manuscript. As Chairman of the Dissertation Committee, I am also deeply indebted to Rich Block for his work with me on this and many previous research projects. Acquisition of the data required the c00peration of many individuals at the federal level of government. Alan Stevens, Chief of the Governments Division,Bureau of the Census, made it possible to match the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) case numbers identifying each public employee strike with the correspondent Census jurisdiction identification number. This enabled an identification of the characteristics of the labor organization calling the strike with the actual jurisdiction taking the strike. Assistance from Larry Curran of the Governments Division was also particularly helpful in this regard. ii From the Department of Labor, Division of Industrial Relations, Gene Becker assisted with the acquisition of machine readable data files containing responses to the 1975-1978 Work StOppage Questionnaire. Evelyn Traylor from this Division was responsible for constructing a coding book for this data. In addition, she spent many hours clarifying for me the meaning and source of these data. John Bonner, Chief, Division of Public Sector Labor Relations, Department of Labor, also provided considerable insight into relevant issues from a public policy point of view. The direction of this project was influenced greatly by these recommendations. This study required the acquisition of many large machine readable data sets. Generous research support from the National Association of Schools of Public Affairs and Administration/National Association of Counties Personnel Dissertation Fellowship made acquisition of these data possible. Alma Beals from NASPAA was particularly instrumental in facilitating completion of this project. In exchange for a c0py of some of the data purchased from this fellowship grant, Craig Olson from Purdue University kindly provided a copy of the 1977 annual employment data. At the state level of government, helpful comments and reactions were received from Robert Pejorsky from the Michigan Employment Relations Commission, Mr. Queen from Pennsylvania's Bureau of Mediation, and Steve Hunter from iii ’1“ f (I) (U '1 () f) New Jersey's Public Employment Relations Commission. Endless hours of complicated computer programming assistance far beyond the technical capability of the principal investigator were provided by Christopher Brown and Harriet Dhanak of the MSU Politometric Laboratory. Merger of a multitude of large data sets would not have been possible had it not been for their skilled and relentless assistance. Einar Hardin also provided helpful suggestions which facilitated construction of the master data set. I am deeply indebted also to Henry Ng of the Univeristy of Texas, Austin for typing the final manuscript and for his many hours of additional work preparing the tables and figures for inclusion in the final manuscript. Calculation of the number of days idled as a result of a strike was made possible by countless hours of meticulous calculation by Nanette Rodgers who also commiserated with me after each and every computer run inhich was unsuccessful. Her encouragement, and the inspiration from our children, Adrienne and Jonathan, were instrumental to the ultimate completion of this project. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter 1 Toward a Recognition of the Importance of Studying Strike Duration . . . . . . . page The Enhanced Visibility of the Public Employee Strike . . . . . . . . . . page Chapter 2 The Literature on Public Employee strikes 0 O C I O O O O O O O I C O 0 page An Overview of the Research on Public Employee Strike Activity . . . . . . page Public Employee Strike and Public Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page What Does the Research Tell Us? . . . page Chapter 3 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page The Prediction of Strike Activity Using Cost Benefit Theory . . . . . . . . page A Framework for Predicting the Duration of Work StOppages . . . . . . . . . page The General Factors . . . . . . . . . page The Dependent Variable (Sit) . . . . . page The Independent Variables . . . . . . page Expectations of the Union Membership: The Bit Vector . . . . . . . . . . page Relative Wage Changes (CE) . . . . page Relative Wage Levels (RE) . . . . page Internal Wage Comparisons (EV) . . page Constraints on the Employer's Ability To Pay the Concessions Demanded by the Union Membership: The Cit Vector . . . . . . . . . . page Relative Importance of the Wages of the Striking Workers to Total Personnel Costs (WE) . . . . . . page 11 ll 14 18 24 24 28 29 33 34 34 34 36 37 39 39 TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued) The Number of Bargaining Units (NU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page Fiscal Constraints . . . . . . . . . page Fiscal Slack (SL) . . . . . . . . page Local Tax Burden (TB) . . . . . . page The Bargaining Relationship: The Bit Vector . . . . . . . . . . page Number of Employees Involved in the Strike (82) . . . . . . . . . . page Combined Occupational Composition of the Bargaining Unit (CM) . . . . page Firefighter Strikes (FIR) . . . . page Police (POL) . . . . . . . . . . . page Sanitation Strikes (SAN) . . . . . page Health Care Workers (HOS) . . . . page Other Employee Types (0TH) . . . . page Degree of Inessentiality (NS) . . page The Bargaining Environment: The Pit Vector . . . . . . . . . . page Negotiation of the First Agreement (FN) . O O O O O O O 0 O O O O 0 page Union Support for the Work StOppage (US) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page The Issues Under Dispute . . . . . . page Additional Considerations: Where and When - The Ki Vector . . . . . . page t Location . . . . . . . . . . . . . page Season . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page vi 41 42 44 46 46 47 48 48 49 50 51 51 53 53 54 54 57 57 58 TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued) The Public Policy Vector (Lit) . . . page The Court Injunction (IJ) . . . . page Mediation (ME) . . . . . . . . . . page Permissive Strike Law (PL) . . . . page The Expanded Estimating Model . . . page Chapter 4 The Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page The Method of Analysis and the Data . page The Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . page The Bit Variables . . . . . . . . . . page The Pit Variables . . . . . . . . . . page The Kit Variables . . . . . . . . . . page The Cit Variables . . . . . . . . . . page The Insignificance of the Number of Units Variable . . . . . . . . . . page The Duration of Strikes in Towns, Counties and Cities . . . . . . . page The Performance of Other Variables in the Cit Vector . . . . . . . . . . page The Eit Variables . . . . . . . . . . page Some Concluding Considerations . . . . page Chapter 5 Analysis of Public Policy Variables . . page Do Court Injunctions Enhance or Deter the Duration of Strikes? . . . . . . page Do State Compulsory Penalty Laws Make a Difference? . . . . . . . . . . . page The Relationship Between the Injunction and the Number of Strikers . . . . . page vii 6O 61 61 63 72 72 76 79 91 93 96 96 97 100 102 108 114 114 115 118 TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued) The Impact of the Injunction Depending on the Type of Employee . . . . . . page The Permissive Strike Law . . . . . . page The Relationship Between Mediation and Strike Duration . . . . . . . . . . page Chapter 6 Summary of Results and Conclusions . . . page Summary of Significant Findings . . . page Summary and Discussion of Insignificant Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page Rural (RU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . page First Negotiation (FN) . . . . . . . page Winter (WR) . . . . . . . . . . . . page Supplemental Benefit Issue (SB) . . page Compulsory Penalty Laws (PE) . . . . page Injunctions (IJ) . . . . . . . . . . page - The Contributions and Limitations of the Study . . . . . . . . . . . . . page Appendices Appendix A: Variable Descriptions and Predictions . . . . . . . . page Appendix B: Means, Standard Deviations and Data Sources . . . . . page Appendix C: The Correlation Matrix . . page viii 121 124 125 134 134 145 146 147 147 147 148 148 153 156 158 Vbl~ \aq Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 77 The prediction of strike duration (Sit) with and without "employee type" variables (The 412 Sample) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 82 The prediction of strike duration (S. ) when excluding variables drawn from the merged Census data source (The 558 Sample) 0 O O O O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 page 89 Regression results for S. which consider a curvilinear specificatign of size 0 O O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O O O O 0 page 99 The prediction of the duration of strikes occurring in cities, towns and counties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 105 The prediction of strike duration when considering the independent effects of CE and EV . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 106 The independent effect of RE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 117 States with and without compulsory penalty laws (PE), by the number of strike occurrences and the number of injunctions issued (1977-1978) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 120 The Effect of the Court Injunction on the Duration of the Strike (1977-1978) . . . . . . . .‘. . . . . . . . . . page 123 The prediction of strike duration when considering the impact of the injunction (IJ) on teacher strikes (EDU) ix LIST OF TABLES (continued) Table 10 O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O 0 page 126 A comparison of mean values for significant predictors when considering Pennsylvania and Ohio strikes Table 11 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 130 The prediction of strike duration when considering the impact of compulsory mediation provisions in state collective bargaining statutes Table 12 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 135 A comparison of the mean beta weights on variables which were significant in Tables 1 through 6 for strikes occurring in all jurisdiction types and strikes occurring in cities, towns, and counties LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . page 6 Mean Duration of Strikes by Local Government Employees Compared to the Mean Duration of Strikes Figure 1 . (1960-1977) in the Service Industry xi Chapter 1 Toward a Rec0gnition of the Importance of Studying Strike Duration Over the past decade, industrial relations scholars have just begun to examine the determinants of public employee strike activity. Adopting the methodology of the (earlier private sector strike studies, research on public .sector strikes has taken into consideration the multi- ciimensional character of the work stOppage. These dimensions include frequency (number of strikes occurring), breadth (the number of persons involved), and impact (the duration c>r length of the strike). In view of the legal sanctions vvhich prohibit or limit strikes in public employment, the :identification of the determinants of strike frequency has lJeen of particular interest not only to researchers but to public officials as well. One dimension of the strike, its duration, has litrgely been neglected, however. Certainly fifty strikes ‘vfiich.last one day would be less likely to cause concern from a public policy point of view than fifty strikes of fifty days duration, especially if the strikes are by essential employee groups such as the firefighters or the police. The economic costs incurred by workers which result from foregone income can be substantial. High political costs can also be incurred by both marlagement and labor. Long strikes arouse public concern 2 over a potential threat to the health and safety of the community. With protracted strikes, day to day accommodation between the parties which is critical to the successful administration of a contract is temporarily interrupted. This can result in a weakening of the political support held by the union leadership, especially when little progress is being made at the negotiating table. Thus, an enhanced understanding of the causal factors accociated with the duration of the public employee strike would be welcomed by public administrators, unions and scholars alike. Prior efforts to explain the duration of public employee strikes have, unfortunately, been inconclusive. {This has been attributed by some to the use of state level :strike data.2 Problems of interpretation can result when asize deflators are used in studies having states as the Iprimary unit of analysis.3 This technique is designed to (zontrol for the fact that a greater number of strikes (and Ipossibly longer strikes) occur in states which have more Ipublic employees. However, when any of the three strike nneasures (frequency, breadth or duration) is adjusted by Ciividing it by a size proxy such as employment, the perform- Eince of the independent variables in a regression are jJnfluenced both by their relationship with the size proxy fits well as with the strike measure. This procedure can thus IDesult, to the dismay of the researcher, in the discovery of Siigns on coefficients which were unexpected. Cost benefit frameworks are probably better suited (1.: f (Y (I) (3 V‘. “4.. a". ‘4 3 to an explanation of strike occurrences than of strike duration. This is because predictions for many of the variables are a function of whether the vested interests of labor or of management are considered in the assessment of the factor's influence. Theoretically, it remains indeter- minate in many instances whose influence would be expected to dominate. In recognition of these caveats, this study is based on the notion that the duration of the strike is affected by considerations other than environmental condi- tions such as unemployment levels or inflation rates. Four basic factors are considered. These include: (1) the earnings advantage (or disadvantage) of the employee group 'which voted to strike; (2) the fiscal and political charac- teristics of the corresponding jurisdiction taking the strike; (3) the characteristics of the bargaining unit calling the strike; and (4) a vector of variables which characterize the local labor relations environment. In studying duration, it has been observed that the identification of factors which characterize differences across local strike events is essential.5 The bargaining unit initiating the strike will thus be the basic unit of analysis. This orientation is useful because of the emphasis on the duration of specific strike events rather than the mean duration of all strikes occuring within broad geo- graphical areas. Using the 558 strikes in local government 4 bargaining units which occurred during the negotiation or renegotiation of a collective bargaining agreement between January 1, 1977 and October 15, 1978, this study examines the determinants of their duration. In addition to economic, structural and environmental factors, this research considers whether mediation and the court injunction act to reduce (or possibly increase) strike duration. These findings, moreover, will have important, albeit qualified, implications of the establishment of public policies which encourage the involvement of third parties at impasse. The Enhanced Visibility of the Public Employee Strike A central premise of this analysis is that a better understanding of the determinants of strike duration is just as critical at this stage in the emerging deve10pment of a public sector strike theory as are studies emphasizing their occurrence or breadth. Aside from the fact that strikes by public employees are a new phenomenon historically, the scarcity of work on duration is due partly to the fact that less working time has been lost overall than has been observed in private sector employment. Of the 11,109 agree- ments which became effective at all levels of local govern- ment in 1977, 95.9% were settled without a strike. Among the 452 bargaining units which elected to withhold services for at least one day, an average of only 7.7 working days were subsequently lost.6 This is considerably less than the 5 duration of strikes in private sector industries. During calender year 1977, the mean duration of strikes in manu- facturing was 29.4 days, 21.3 days in contract construction, 21.2 days in the services industry, and 30.7 days in finance, insurance and real estate.7 For comparative purposes, it is instructive to compare the strike experience of local government employees with their closest private sector counterparts--the services industry. The secular trend over the past twenty years shows that the mean duration of strikes in the services industry exhibited a slight upward trend. As shown in Figure l, the range in duration was bounded by 11 calender days in 1965 and 33 calender days in 1971. Local government employee strikes, on the other hand, became noticeably longer over this same period. As also shown in Figure l, strikes initiated by local government employees in the early 1960's lasted on the average only two (2) calender days. By the late 1970's, the mean duration of public employee strikes averaged eight (8) calender days. This is less than the overall strike experience in the services industry during 1960 - 1977. Public employee strikes, on the other hand, have become noticeably larger. In addition to evidence that supports the prOpo- sition that the public employee strike is lengthening, there are also reasons for believing that strikes will become more frequent in the 1980's. Consider, for instance, recent developments which provide added incentives to public Figure 1 Mean Duration of Strikes by Local Government Employees Compared to the Mean Duration of Strikes in the Service Industry 1 960-1 977 Mean Duration in Calendar Days 33 2 1 20 ‘ a" 1 9 ,o .0 .0 .0 18 '60 '61 ’62 '63 '64 '65 '86 '67 '68 '69 '70 '71 '72 '73 '74 '75 '76 ‘77 Year Data Sources. BLS, Work Stoppages in Government, 1977 (Report 554): Work Stoppages in Government. 1975 (Report 483); Work Stoppages rn Government. 1974 (Report 453); Work Stoppages In Government. 1973 (Report 437); Work Stoppages in Government. 1972 (Report 434), Work Stoppdgns Government Employees, 1942 1961 (Report 348); Work Stoppagos by Industry Group. 1950-1977. BLS Bulletin 2032, Analysts 01 Work Sloppages. 1977. Mean Duration of Mean Duration of u—_—Q Strikes by Loca| raga-canon... Strikes in the Government Employees Services Industry 7 employers to take strikes. Tightening fiscal constraints have begun to plague many local governments in the 1970's. As a result, employers are now more willing to accept strikes because they result in a savings of expenditures without a commensurate reduction in revenues. Further, a once pOpular alternative to the strike in public employment, compulsory arbitration, has recently been criticized.9 This is primarily because arbitration awards have been viewed by some employers as too generous.10 Anticipation of an arbitration settlement which could be unacceptable would be expected to enhance the attractiveness of taking a strike. The strike during the decade of the 1980's is thus eXpected to become better accepted as a viable Ineans of settling public employee disputes among less essen- tial employee groups.ll Public employee strikes may thus become not only longer, but also more frequent. The potential contribution of studies which predict the frequency of the strike can thus be bolstered by a better understanding of the determi- nants of the duration of the strike. As frequency studies continue to be of interest to public policy officials, it is hoped this study will spark interest in further studying duration. As previously observed, one concern of this study is to evaluate the impact on strike duration, if any, of 12 mediation and the court injunction. It is important, therefore, to review the research not only on public employee 8 strike activity, but also the research which evaluates the impact of public policy on strikes. This review is presented in Chapter 2. Chapter 3 presents a discussion of a general model which is used to identify factors expected to contrib- ute to an explanation of duration. Chapter 4 discusses the results when the variables defined in Chapter 3 are entered in multiple regressions. Chapter 5 further considers and analyzes the empirical relationship between the public policy factors selected for examination and strike duration. Con- clusions of the study are presented in Chapter 6. 9 Footnotes (Chapter 1) 1 The seminal work on public employee strike activity was by John F. Burton & Charles E. Krider, "The Incidence of Strikes in Public Employment," in Daniel S. Hamermesh, Labor in the Public and Nonprofit Sectors (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975), pp. 135-185. For a more thorough discussion of the literature, see Chapter 2. As noted by one set of researchers, "In some cases, state boundaries may be artificial delimiters of the Operation of metrOpolitan and regional influences." James L. Perry & Leslie J. Berkes, "Predicting Local Government Strike Activity: An Exploratory Analysis," Western Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 30 (December, 1977), p. 527. Robert N. Stern, "MethodolOgical Issues in Quantitative Strike Analysis," Industrial Relations, Vol. 17, No. 1 (February, 1978). For a general discussion of this problem, see Malcolm Fisher, Measurement of Labour Disputes and Their Economic Effects (Orgafiization for Economic Co-Operation and Development, (1973). An alternative approach is to enter the size proxy as an independent (rather than a divisor of the dependent) variable. This tends to raise the explanatory power of the regression at the expense of reducing the significance of the other independent variables in the equation due to high multicolinearity. 5 Robert N. Stern, "Intermetropolitan Patterns of Strike Frequency," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 2 (January, 1976), p. 233. 6 U.S. Department of Commerce & U.S. Department of Labor, Labor Management Relations in State and Local Government, 1977 Census of Governments, Vol. 3, No. 3 (Washington, D.C., 1979). 7 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Analysis of Work StOppages, 1977, Bulletin 2032, Table 14 (G.P.O.: 1977), pp. 24—28. 10 8 Theodore W. Kheel, "Resolving Deadlocks without Banning Strikes," in Joseph Loewenberg & Michael H. Moskow (eds.). Collective Bargaining in Government (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1972), p. 262. See also Robert C. Rodgers, "A Replication of the Burton Krider Model of Public Employee Strike Activity," Industrial Relations Research Association Series, (1981), pp. 241-251. The following remark is also reflective of this emerging point of View: "Until only recently the public supported a variety of anti-strike measures in the governmental sector, but lately they have shown an increased willingness to take at least some strikes." from David Lewin, "Collective Bargaining and the Right to Strike," in A. Lawrence Chickering (ed.), Public Emplgyee Unions: A Study of the Crisis in Public Sector Labor Relations (San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary StudIes, 1976), PP. 145-146; for a report of a cost savings which accrued to a city government as a result of a strike, see George A. Sipel, Public Management, V01. 58, No. 2 (February, 1976), pp. 4-5. 9 See J. Joseph Loewenberg, "Compulsory Arbitration for Police and Firefighters in Pennsylvania in 1968," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 23 (April, 1970), pp. 367- 379. 10 Compulsory arbitration, for instance, has been cited by the Mayor of Detroit, Michigan as a primary cause for this city's recent financial difficulties. 11 This does not mean, however, that the use of compulsory arbitration schemes, whether conventional or any one of the many forms of final offer arbitration, will necessarily subside. Some experts in the field have suggested that they are likely to become even more frequently used mechanisms for resolving public employee disputes in the 1980's. Graig Overton, "The Climate for Collective Bargaining in General Purpose Local Government in the 1980's," Industrial Relations Research Association Series (September, 1981), pp. 290-295. 12 A research agenda in the 1980's included the need to learn more about the effectiveness impact of third parties in the resolution of labor management disputes. U.S. Department of Labor, Labor Management Relations Research Priorities for the 1980's, Final Report to the Secretary of Labor, (GPO: I980), p. 46. Chapter 2 The Literature on Public Employee Strikes An Overview of the Research on Public Employee Strike Activity As observed, we have little understanding of the determinants of the duration of strikes in the public sector. As will be evident in this discussion of the literature, the number of studies are limited and the evidence inconclusive. While time series analyses of private sector strike activity have been common since 1952,1 our brief experience with public sector strikes for the most part has precluded similar analyses due to a lack of a sufficient number of observations.2 Cross sectional analyses of interstate differences in public employee strikes have, on the other hand, not been precluded. In their cross sectional study, Burton and Krider found the performance of the fifteen variables selected for examination across multiple strike measures, including duration, to be inconsistent and disappointing. "Most of the variation among states in strike activity in a particular year," they reported, "cannot be explained by our variables, and those variables that appear important in one year often are unimportant or have an Opposite effect in other years."3 The explanatory power of their multiple regressions was low, especially considering the 11 12 large number of predictors which were used. Inconsistent signs were also found on many coefficients across the four years of their analysis (1968 through 1971). As noted by the researchers, this may have been due to the high multi- colinearity among the variables selected for examination. Results when using duration as the dependent strike measure were especially unilluminating. Referring to the inability of previous research to explain duration, the authors subsequently questioned the merit of future attempts to study strike duration. Duration may, in fact, be "a particularly erratic aSpect of strike activity."4 An important benefit of this study is that it will provide an empirical basis for evaluating this concern. In a subsequent cross sectional study by Perry and Berkes,5 the develOpment of a theory of public sector strikes was avoided in light of "the paucity of previous research and the general lack of agreement about deter- minants of local employee strike activity." Rather than making predictions about the relationship of specific variables with multiple measures of strike activity, they factor analyzed 40 variables which were hypothesized to influence public employee strikes.6 These variables were divided into four general categories: macro-environmental variables, governmental sector variables, public employment variables and legal policy variables. Factor loadings suggested to the authors ten plausible groupings. These were identified as follows, with examples 13 of the variables associated with each factor in paren- theses: (l) urbanization—industrialization (percent of the pOpulation which is urban, percent in non—agricultural establishments), (2) union influence in the private sector (union membership as a percent of non-agriculture employ- ment), (3) race-poverty (percent of the pOpulation below a "low income level"), (4) fiscal effort (govern- ment expenditures per capita, government expenditures per $1,000 personal income), (5) prOperty tax reliance (per capita prOperty tax revenues, prOperty tax revenues as a percent of expenditures), (6) local employee status (ratio of government employee earnings to private sector employee earnings, local government employment as a percent of non-agriculture employment), (7) past strike activity (number of public employees involved in work stOppages (1958-1968, logged), (8) local reliance (percentage of government revenue raised by local governments, percent of state and local government expenditures), (9) pro- fessionalism (prOportion of cities with a city manager form of government, percent of the pOpulation within city manager cities), (10) facilitation of bargaining, consisting largely of provisions in the law (sc0pe of bargaining, unfair labor practice provisions, union security provisions). After generating "factor variables" for each of the above ten groupings, the reconstructed variables were entered into multiple regressions for each of the 14 strike measures selected for examination. For one measure, the number of days idle per non-education, local government employee, more than 50% of the variance was explained by the entry of the factor variables listed above.7 The one and only significant predictor, however, was the local employee status factor. A predicted negative sign for this factor turned out to be positive. The absence of a control for the size of the bargaining unit makes interpretation of these findings subject to considerable qualification. As observed, the frequency of strikes is theoretically and empirically related to the number of employees negotiating or rene- gotiating agreements and also to the number seeking reCOgnition status. It is thus not surprising to find that there are more strikes in states which have more public employees. If it is also true that strikes in the larger states tend, on the average, to be longer, then the local employee status variable used by Perry and Berkes may actually have been proxying the number of local public employees in the state. The author's description of and subsequent prediction for this factor may thus have been misspecified. Public Employee Strike and Public Policy In a third study, Perry considered the direct impact of collective bargaining laws on public employee 15 strike activity for three categories of employee groups: teachers, local government employees and state government employees.8 Positive, although generally insignificant, correlations were found between multiple measures of strikes and union security provisions in state public employment bargaining laws.9 Perry expected positive coefficients, since union bargaining power and union expectations should be greater when union security provisions are in effect. One plausible explanation for the finding of insignificant coefficients is the fact that bargaining power may not be linearly related to strike activity. If unions with a high degree of bargaining power are able to obtain concessions without striking, while unions with relatively low levels of bargaining power seldom strike because they lack the necessary strength, then the relationship between strikes and bargaining power would be curvilinear. A positive and significant relationship between strikes and union security provisions would thus be seen only when considering labor organizations which were weak or "moderately strong."10 A central conclusion of the Perry study was that state enacted legislation has had little effect on public employee strike activity.‘ This observation is consistent with similarly insignificant results obtained by Burton and Krider on a set of legal variables which were also expected to be positively associated with strike activity. 16 In the Burton and Krider, the Perry and Berkes and the Perry studies, a dummy variable was created to represent the presence (or absence) of a provision in state legislation covering public employees. In the factor analytic study by Perry and Berkes, eleven provisions found in state laws were considered. These consisted of the existence of an impasse procedure, a grievance procedure, provisions pertaining to the legality of strikes, manage- ment rights, the sc0pe of bargaining, unfair labor practices, union security, bargaining rights, unit determination, rules of procedure and the establishment of a labor relations administrative policy. Burton & Krider considered, among other factors, the existence of a third party procedure law and a strike prohibition law. Perry considered the presence (or absence) of strike policies and, as noted, union security provisions. He also used a comprehensive index which was constructed by summing across twelve selected collective bargaining provisions in the state law.11 In none of these studies was a consistently significant relationship reported between the legal variables and strikes. Legal indexes used in prior research, regardless of whether they were constructed to capture a particular provision in a collective bargaining law or the compre- hensiveness of such a law, are not factors which necessarily have a direct impact on strike activity. A provision in a state's collective bargaining law may require the l7 mediation of all disputes unsettled by the termination date of the contract. Nonetheless, many disputes which reach impasse at this stage are settled without the assistance of mediators.12 Courts may be empowered, under state law, to deliver cease and desist injunctions. Injunctions can not be issued by the courts in most states, however, unless the employer is willing to file a formal complaint. The courts do, of course, deliver cease and desist injunctions, but these orders, eSpecially without effective enforcement, may be ingored more often than obeyed. This response, if it exists, would, over time, reduce the effectiveness of penalty provisions as a strike deterrent. Two explanations are possible for the absence of a significant relationship between laws and strikes. As observed, there is reason to believe that laws do not necessarily have a direct impact on the actual strike behavior of the parties. Alternatively, the direction of the effect, if and when it is realized, may simply be equivocal. Strike prohibition laws may serve their intended purpose by significantly reducing strike occurrences, eSpecially in states which complement this law with compulsory arbitration. In states which have no compulsory arbitration Option available to the parties, the strike prohibition law may actually encourage militant behavior. Public policy may thus act both to encourage 18 and discourage the duration of strikes.13 The theoretical possibility of this two-edged effect is, similarly, a limitation of the basic frameworks used in previous empirical studies.14 An attempt has been made in this study to consider factors, such as the involvement of mediators and the issuance of court injunctions, which are used to limit the duration of actual strike occurrences. This eliminates the problems associated with considering the impact Of legal variables which may not have a direct impact on strikes. This approach does not, however, avoid the theoretical ambiguity inherent in the direction of their impact. The empirical relationship between selected Iaublic policy factors and strike duration will be considered :in.greater detail in Chapter 5. What Does the Research Tell Us? A recurring theme in these studies is that little ies actually known about the determinants of public sector eunployee strike activity. Perry and Berkes suggested that "Emalitical and organizational models" ought to be illcorporated in the construction of a public sector strike tflaeory.15 Their findings, however, precluded a precise iJiterpretation of what is meant by political or even <3rganizational considerations. While Perry and Berkes exPlained more of the variation in duration than the other researchers, the sign on the coefficient of their only 19 significant predictor was inconsistent with their expectation. Perry expected positive and significant coefficients on his public policy variables, but discovered that correlations with his strike measures were not significant. Unlike the Perry and Berkes and the Perry studies, Burton and Krider specified a model which provided a themaretical basis for making predictions. Like Perry, they considered the impact of state policy indicators on the: incidence of strikes. Environmental and organizational factumrs, however, were also taken into consideration. Even wit}: this more fully specified model, their overall results, as 111 the Perry study, were inconclusive. Multiple strike measures were used in these studies. Across measures, no attempt was made to determine Statxistically whether or not these strike measures were captulring similar or different dimensions of the strike. Wit}; an implicit assumption that the strike measures were homogeneous, no differences were taken into consideration in what; was expected in the performance of the coefficients on the independent variables when using duration as Opposed to frequency or breadth.:L6 If there are basic differences across the various dimensions of the strike, including its occurrence, breadth and duration, the develOpment of a different model and the selection of different independent predictors for each Of the strike measures would have been preferable.17 The 20 lack of an understanding of the general characteristics which differentiate these measures has thus far precluded this approach, however. Treating all of the dimensions as equivalent, then, identical independent variables were used in prior studies to predict all dimensions of the strike. It was assumed that the framework develOped to predict strike frequency was theoretically relevant to examinations of the other strike dimensions, including duration. This study takes a different approach. A model is prOposed which has theoretical relevance for one and only one of the strike dimensions, duration. Factors which would be expected to influence the decision to engage in or take a strike may be different, presumably, from the determinants of the strike's duration. An important implication from the empirical results of prior studies is that strike frequency mode ls have not been particularly useful frameworks for Predicting strike duration. The model developed in this Study, to be discussed in Chapter 3, thus modifies the frameworks which have been the cornerstone of work in this area . 21 Footnotes (Chapter 2) This research, an often cited work in the literature, is that of Albert Rees, "Industrial Conflict and Business Fluctuations," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 60, No. 5 (October, 1952) . This line of empirical investigation began with Alvin Hansen's publication in 1921 of "Cycles of Strikes," American Economic Review, Vol. 11, No. 4 (December, 192D: pp. 616-621. One time series study has been reported by Andrew R. Weintraub and Robert J. Thornton, "Why Teachers Strike: The Economic and Legal Determinants," Journal of Collective Negotiations, Vol. 5, No. 3 (1976), pp. 193-206. PublIc employee strike activity has been worthy of note since 1965 when the Bureau of Labor Statistics first began disaggregating strikes by public employees at the state level. Before this time, there were relatively few strike occurrences. John F. Burton & Charles E. Krider, "The Incidence of Strikes in Public Employment," in Dan S. Hamermesh, ijor in the Public and Nonprofit Sectors (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975), p. 170. Ibid., p. 149, p. 156. The difficulty inherent in predict- lng uration was further delineated during a personal conversation with John Burton in Atlanta, Georgia, December 28, 1979. James L. Perry & Leslie J. Berkes, "Predicting Local Government Strike Activity: An Exploratory Analysis," Western Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 30 (December, 1977), p. 5121. 6 The use of a factor analytic technique, a priori, assumes tfhat the factor components are orthogonal. No theoretical Justification is provided for why one might expect this to be the case and there is no reason to believe that Good predictors of strikes would necessarily be uncorrelated. 7 Perry and Berkes, unfortunately, fail to specify if their strike measures pertain to education employees, to non- education employees, or to both. 22 8 James L. Perry, "Public Policy and Public Employee Strikes," Industrial Relations, Vol. 16, No. 3 (October, 1977)! Pp. 27§-282. 9 This study is not clear on which laws were actually examined, i.e., state laws covering local employees, state laws covering teachers, state laws covering state employees, or some combination thereof. 10 Burton and Krider, Op. cit., p. 153. 11 This comprehensive index was initially proposed by Thomas Kochan, "Correlates of State Public Employee Bargaining Laws," Industrial Relations, Vol. 12, No. 3 (October, 1973). PP. 322-327. Kochan finds positive correlations between a comprehensive index of collective bargaining laws and the breadth of strikes by police, firefighters, teachers, local government employees and state government employees. Only the correlation with teacher strikes was, however, significant. 12 This conclusion is evident from a comparison of state laws which require mediation and the actual use of mediation across all states. It is just as common for states Without such laws to involve mediators at impasse as it is for states with these laws. A more detailed discussion of this anomaly can be found in Chapter 5. l3 Kochan and Wheeler report that the militant tactics of firefighters, as captured by such considerations as slow- downs, sickouts and picketing, were not related to three legal provisions in the state bargaining law or to an index constructed to represent the comprehensiveness of the law. See Thomas A. Kochan & Hoyt Wheeler, "Municipal Collective Bargaining: A Model and Analysis of Bargaining Outcomes," Edustrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 1 (October, 1975). 14 For a reaffirmation of this theme, see Robert C. Rodgers, "Replication of the Burton-Krider Model of Public Employee Strike Activity," IRRA Series, 1981. Strike activity (or the "militant tactic") has, on the other hand, been recently used as a predictor of collective bargaining out— comes. See Thomas A. Kochan & Hoyt Wheeler, "Municipal Collective Bargaining: A Model and Analysis of Bargaining Outcomes," Op. cit.; Paul F. Gerhart, "Determinants of 23 Bargaining Outcomes in Local Government Labor Negotiations," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 3 (March, 1976), pp. 331-351. 15 Perry & Berkes, op. cit., p. 527. 16 It has been reported in a study of strikes in the private sector that the same predictors perform very differently, depending on the particular strike measure being examined. For a comparison of the performance of the same predictor when using nine different strike specifications, see Jack Skeels, "Measures of U.S. Strike Activity," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 24, No. 4 (July, 1971), pp. 515—525. 17 Robert N. Stern, "Toward an Empirical Merger: SociolOgical and Economic Conceptions of Strike Activity," Twenty-Eighth Annual IRRA Meeting (1975), p. 66. Chapter 3 The Model The Prediction of Strike Activity Using Cost Benefit Theory It is unfortunate that, as noted by McClean, "there is not a sufficiently well-develOped theory of the role and determinants of the strike in industry specific terms from which one can develop a genuinely satisfactory model."1 As noted, this caveat is eSpecially evident for the one dimension of the strike under consideration here, its duration. One approach, develOped by Ashenfelter and Johnson, has been used with some success in a number of previous studies of public and private sector strike activity.2 A guiding premise of their analysis is that labor and manage- ment, having complete and undistorted information, are rational decision makers. It is then hypothesized that the strike is continued as long as the present value of "holding out" exceeds the estimated cost of "giving in." The impact of the strike event itself on the decision making of both parties is thus taken into consideration. If, for instance, unemployment insurance or Umion strike benefits are received, the propensity to "hold out" is enhanced because the net cost to the workers <>f remaining on strike is reduced. On the management side,. 24 25 political costs are incurred as the strike interrupts essential services. Alternatively, economic benefits can accrue to the employer, since expenditures are averted without a commensurate reduction in revenues. These simultaneous effects should offset one another. This model is based on the assumption that decision making by labor and management will be both rational and purposeful. It is assumed, moreover, that during the give and take of negotiations, the union leadership and the employer should be able to identify the terms of an economic settlement which are mutually advantageous. Strikes subsequently occur, they hypothesize, to square the expectations of the union membership with what the employer is able and willing to pay. The behavior of union members is thereby viewed as irrational.3 A decision to strike is not in their best long term interests, but workers are believed nonetheless to be willing to strike after the expiration of the previous contract when the offer falls short of the expectation.4 The model of strike duration developed for purposes of this analysis modifies the Ashenfelter and Johnson framework as follows. All parties which have a vested interest in the successful negotiation of a contract (management, union leadership, the union membership, and the public at large) are assumed to be fully capable of rational decision making. Thus, the behavior of the union nmmbership is believed to be no less rational or purposeful 26 than the behavior of the union leadership who are elected to represent their interests or the public employer from whom they are seeking concessions. This strike duration model, developed in the following section of this chapter, is similar to the framework adopted by Ashenfelter and Johnson to the extent that the decision to abort or continue the strike is assumed to be a rational process. Both models take into consideration the interests of more than one party and thereby recognize that something can be gained (or lost) by each as a result of an additional day of idleness. As observed, however, this approach lends itself to the generation of a variety of competing hypotheses. "It is difficult to generate unambiguous predictions regarding the effects of environmental variables on the dispute resolution process. This is especially problematic...since those variables that increase union militancy or resistance in bargaining may have the offsetting effect of reducing management resistance."5 A consideration such as the ability of the employer to meet union demands, a factor of central impor— tance to this type of theory, has an ambiguous effect. On the one hand, a greater ability to pay enhances the prOpensity of the employer to "give in." This should lead to a reduction in the duration of the strike. 27 Conversely, a greater ability to pay also enhances labor's incentive to "hold out" for concessions that otherwise might not have been expected. This lends support to the expectation of an increase in duration. It is thus not surprising that when using this model, insignificant coefficients on many of the variables selected for examination have been found.6 A further limitation of this approach is the implicit assumption that the decision to end the strike is tied to a contract settlement which is acceptable to a majority of the voting membership. In the empirical application of their model, Ashenfelter and Johnson adjust their dependent variable, the number of strikes beginning in a quarter, by the number of contract expirations during this same period. There are many instances, especially in the public sector, when workers return to their jobs without a contract.7 Moreover, the extent to which the decision to end a strike is tied to a rational consideration of the costs of agreeing versus the costs of disagreeing is questionable,8 given that the actual costs involved are often discernable only after the strike has ended and after a final settlement has been reached. In studies which adOpted the Ashenfelter and Johnson framework, cost-benefit analysis thus became a useful tool for explaining strike frequency.9 There are compelling reasons for believing that cost-benefit analysis should also be relevant to the prediction of strike duration. 28 The costs to each of the parties of engaging in long strikes should, after all, be a relevant consideration. Ashenfelter and Johnson skirt the indeterminant predictions suggested by a cost-benefit framework by assuming away the rationality of the union membership and by considering primarily the net costs of the strike to the employer. Moreover, their primary interest was in being able to predict the frequency of strikes in private, rather than public, employment. When considering the impact of cost factors to labor or to the public, important considerations for a study of public sector strikes, the net impact of cost considerations becomes unavoidably problematic. A Framework for Predicting the Duration of Work StOppages In recoqnition of the problems associated with adopting a cost-benefit model for a study of public employee strike duration, the Ashenfelter and Johnson framework has been modified and extended. Additional considerations which rational actors would be expected to take into account, including some that are Specifically relevant to the public sector, are incorporated into the model. As noted in Chapter 1, it is important to consider factors which are Specifically relevant to the local bargaining situation. Because the basic unit of analysis is the bargaining unit which elected to initiate 29 a strike, Spurious statistical relationships which result from using deflated strike measures will not be a problem. As in previous strike studies, multiple regression will be the primary statistical technique. Based on the foregoing review of the literature, five general factors (including a control vector) have been identified for examination. These are discussed below. The General Factors In this model, the duration of the strike is, in part, a positive function of the difference between the union membership's expectation of the attainable wage concession and the final offer of the last, pre-strike negotiation round. Other considerations equal, enhanced expectations should lead to longer strikes.10 It is thus assumed that final pre-strike offers analyzed across strikes do not have significant moderating affects on expectation levels. In collective bargaining, expectations are primarily influenced by the earnings of comparable employees working in neighboring or contiguous jurisdictions. The greater the discrepancy between the perception of what the union membership believes constitutes an acceptable contract offer (as influenced by what comparable employees have been able to obtain) and the terms offered, the greater is the overall level of discontent.11 This level of 30 discontent, in turn, Should directly affect the duration of the strike. A vector (Bit) of three variables has thus been selected to capture the overall expectation level of bargaining unit i employees who elected to initiate a strike during time period t. The construction of the variables associated with this vector is guided by the belief that the behavior of the union membership and the union leadership is significantly affected by comparisons with the earnings obtained by other, similar employee groups.12 Data constraints in prior studies precluded the possibility of considering any factor other than the impact on strikes of mean earnings. A typical measure, for instance, was the mean earnings of all non-education employees in a state. As reported in Chapter 2, however, inconsistent or unexpected Signs on all variables have been the rule, rather than the exception, in these studies. This study builds on these results by relating the earnings of the employee group which elected to strike to the earnings of other, similar employee groups working for other employers as well as to the mean earnings of other employee groups working for the same employer. It is thus not the absolute level of earnings, but the earnings differential which may, it is believed, be the relevant factor. Variable Specifications for the Bit vector and for the other vectors to be considered in this study will be discussed in the following section of this chapter. 31 Economic and political constraints also have an unmistakable impact on the ability and willingness of an employer to make concessions during the course of a strike. In a. Jrecent study of the collective bargaining experiences across nine school districts in California, Charles Perry concluded that the economic hardship experienced by six of tiles districts studied (as measured by a marked decline in the tax base, an absolute drOp in tax support of varying typess, and the failure of the community to adjust prOperty tax JJBVieS upward) was associated with the severity of the strikes in those communities.13 Strikes in these districts, he suggested, were "both prolonged and bitter." Expectations thus affect the magnitude of the concessions sought by labor, while restrictions on the employer affect the magnitude of the concessions offered durirng the course of the strike. A vector (Cit) of four variables has been selected to represent the economic and pOlitical constraints confronted by the bargaining unit i emPlOyer during time period t. These variables are not proxies for the financial capacity of the employer to make concessions. Financial cOnditions of public entities are particularly difficult to aScertain, given the political nature of the budget process and the complexity of public accounting procedures. Further, even if accurate measures of an employer's ability to pay were attainable, the net effect of these factors remains indeterminant. As observed, there are reasons for 32 believing that strikes may be longer, just as there are reasons for thinking that they may be shorter, when considering the financial capacity of an employer to award concessions. Some of the variables to be considered in the Cit vector do not have Signs which can be predicted a pric>ri. This does not mean, however, that their ultimate imPEiCt will necessarily be inconsequential. This is an empnirical, rather than a theoretical question at this point in 1:he early develOpment of a theory of strike duration. The recognition of economic factors alone, however, is not expected to be particularly successful in eXplaining strike duration. Existing evidence suggests that economic considerations are actually better determinants of strike occurrence than of strike duration. "Efforts to explain duration with an economic model have invariably explained less variance and iden- tified fewer significant variables than similar models of frequency and breadth."14 Moreover, it was suggested in Chapter 1 that one Of the problems with the methodology used in prior strike Studies is a failure to take into consideration the overall Context in which the labor relations system functions.15 Accordingly, noneconomic considerations have been identified and subsequently grouped into three vectors. These are Bit (the bargaining relationship in unit i during time period 33 t), Pit (the bargaining environment in unit i during time period t), and K121; (other relevant factors). Having discussed the general purposes served by vectors Ei't' Cit, Bit’ discrussion of the dependent variable, as well as the Pit' and Kit' we now turn to a inderpendent variables which are associated with each vector, respectively. The Dependent Variable (Sit) The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) calculates the number of idle days which resulted from a strike by counting the total number of days lost from the beginning of the strike to the end and by subtracting all weekends and holidays which fall within this time period. Accordingly, Strikes beginning on Monday and terminating on the following Sunday are reported as 5 days of idleness for all employee grcups. Firefighters, police and hospitals, on the other hand, are required to provide service on a continuous, 24 hour a day basis. Sit' the number of working days lost as a result of a strike, is thus the equivalent of the calender duration of the strike for nurses, firefighters and police. The coding scheme used to estimate the number of work days idled for the remaining employee groups is identical to the procedure employed by the BLS to calculate working days 34 idles- Log (Sit) will be used for purposes of the statistical analysis, since its statistical parameters represent a more normalized distribution. A description of these parameters can be found in Appendix B. The Independent Variables EXpectations of the Union Membership The E. Vector zt Relative wage Changes (CE) This variable measures the historical gain (or loss) of the earnings received by the striking bargaining unit vis-a-vis the wages of comparable employee groups in other jurisdictions within the same state. It is assumed that comparisons are made by public employees with their occupational counterparts, i.e. firefighters compare their wage position relative to that of other firefighters, teachers compare their earnings with the wages of other teachers working in neighboring school districts. One would expect a decline in strike duration when expectations for an acceptable contract award (based on what comparable employee groups were able to Obtain) rose less rapidly than the rate of increase in previous contracts awarded to the Strikers. One variable used in this study to represent GXpectations measures the expansion (or contraction) of the 35 wages; awarded to other, comparable employee groups.16 Over the iiiscal period prior to the strike, this is defined as the change in the mean, monthly earnings of the comparable employee group in the same state. This measure, as one indicator of expectations, takes into account the extent to veriCh wage concessions historically obtained by other emplrayees may have generated differing levels of discontent. Thus , CE=(ME -ME )/ME 7‘; t-J 75—] Where: MB is the mean monthly earnings of comparable, full time employee groups working in the same state; t is October, 1977 for strikes initiated between October 15, 1977 and October 15, 1978 t is October 15, 1976 for all strikes initiated between January 1, 1977 and October 15, 1977.17 AS noted previously, this is a refinement of earnings measures used in earlier studies in that it takes into consideration the fact that worker expectations Should be affected by changes in the compensation awards received 36 18 by other, comparable employees. CE should thus have a positaive sign. The operational definitions for CE and the othexr' variables to be used in this analysis are presented in Appendix A . Relative Wage Levels (RE) Although bargaining history Should directly affect the extent to which workers are dissatisfied, a compuarison of existing, pre-strike wage levels obtained by comparable employee groups should also be a relevant factor. EXpecrtations of the membership are thus affected not only by past, but by current circumstances as well. The ratio of the mean monthly earnings of comparable employee groups in the same state (RE) to the mean monthly earnings of the bargéiining unit which elected to strike should also be posiizively associated with strike duration. Thus: RE= (MEt/Et) Where: MB is the mean monthly earnings of comparable, full time employee groups employed by jurisdictions located in the same state; E is the mean monthly earnings of the bargaining unit which elected to initiate a strike 37 during time period t; t is October, 1977 for strikes initiated between October 15, 1977 and October 15, 1978; t is October 15, 1976 for all strikes initiated between January 1, 1977 and October 14, 1977. Internal Wage Comparisons (EV) The maintenance of the differential in earnings across employee groups with differing skill levels is also affected by the perceived equity of pay within the same jurisdiction. It is important to the higher skilled emPlCJyee groups to maintain differentials. The variation in compensation levels, however, can be narrowed by awarding incrreases in pay for all employee groups by fixed absolute, ratller than fixed percentage increments. In so doing, employers are able to offer higher, and therefore more attractive initial salaries for entry level positions. A loss in the relative earnings advantage among skilled emPloyees Should enhance expectations for this group. The less skilled employee groups would be expected to respond Similarly to the award of greater relative increases to the higher skilled employees. The variable EV, the percent change over the fiscal year period before the strike in the mean monthly 38 earnings of all other employee groups working in the jurisdiction which took the strike to the mean monthly earnings of the bargaining unit which elected to initiate the strike, should thus have a positive sign. Therefore, EV Where: MJ is the mean monthly earnings of all full time employee groups working for the same employer; is the pre-strike, mean monthly earnings of full time bargaining unit employees who elected to strike; is October, 1977 for strikes initiated between October 15, 1977 and October 15, 1978; is October 15, 1976 for all strikes initiated between January 1, 1977 and October 14, 1977. 39 Constraints on the Employer's Ability to Pay the Concessions Demanded by the Union Membership The Cit Vector Relative Importance of the Wages of the Striking Workers to Total Personnel Costs (WB) Considerable emphasis has been placed in the collective bargaining literature on the economic bargaining power derived by a small number of organized workers whose salaries are a small component of total Operating costs.19 Fewer strikes are expected when the wage bill of the striking employees is low relative to total costs because of the greater relative bargaining power attributed to organized labor in this instance.20 "Where the prOportion of labor cost is small, it may not seem worth while for the management to refuse to co-Operate with the employees unless there are irritating union rules limiting the freedom of management."21 As an argument which is relevant to explanations Of strike frequency, how is the prOportion of labor cost to total cost related to strike duration? If this ratio is small, the employer Should have greater financial capacity to sponsor the employment of temporary strike replacements. The successful recruitment of replacements may require wage offers which exceed, by a considerable margin, the wages 40 paid to regular employees. When few workers are involved, the employer may have the financial capacity to pay high enough wages to attract temporary replacements, hOping that this will force the strikers back to their jobs. If, on the other hand, the component of labor costs of the striking employee group to total labor costs is high, as is the case with teachers, hiring strike replacements becomes more difficult. Unlike the former situation, the additional economic resources required to recruit replacement personnel can be substantial. Also, a sufficient number of qualified personnel, especially if the striking group is large, may Simply be unavailable. Employees comprising a relatively small component of labor costs who are threatened with strike replacements may be cajoled into "giving in" earlier. Further, it may be more rational for the employer to settle rather than hire temporary replacements. If a heightened level of conflict results during the give and take of negotiations, resistance to "giving in" could, on the other hand, be bolstered. The interplay among these considerations: the greater bargaining power of labor when labor costs are minimal, the greater capacity of the employer to recruit strike replacements, and the recognition by labor that the employer may have the capability to make concessions, is indeed complex. If the prOportion of labor costs of the strikers to total labor costs acts primarily as a constraint on the 41 employer, strikes should be longer. But this variable may also proxy the ability of an employer to grant the concessions demanded. As such, its effect is indeterminant. WB, the ratio of the wage bill of the striking bargaining unit to total wage and salary expenditures of the jurisdiction taking the strike, is the measure selected to represent the component of labor costs to the overall labor costs incurred by the employer. Since public employers are labor intensive, the denominator of W8 is total labor costs, not total costs.22 The construction of this variable is intended to represent a financial constraint on the employer. However, to the extent that WB also represents the ability of the employer to make concessions, its Sign must remain indeterminant. The Number of Bargaining Units (NU) While the short run costs of granting a favorable contract to organized employees who account for a small component of overall costs is minimal, long termt costs may be formidable. Public administrators who are required to negotiate with more than one bargaining unit have reason to be hesitant to award favorable contracts to smaller units.23 Agreements which favor one employee group can become the contract pattern during subsequent negotiation rounds. There also exists the possibility that a contract could be used by the larger and more powerful labor unions as a bargaining strategy to obtain more favorable contract 42 terms for themselves. The number of bargaining units in a jurisdiction should therefore be a practical constraint on an employer's willingness to make concessions. This consideration is captured by the variable (NU), the number of recognized bargaining units in the jurisdiction taking the strike. NU is expected to be positively associated with duration. Fiscal Constraints Highly constrained financial conditions may give strength to the employer to "hold out." This would suggest longer strikes, ceteris paribus. If the financial resources required to meet demands are simply unavailable, labor may be convinced early in the course of the strike that their cause is futile. Two variables have been Operationalized to capture the extent to which an employer may be constrained financially and politically to make concessions. These are fiscal slack (SL) and the local tax burden (TB). A discussion and Operationalization of these variables follow. Fiscal Slack (SL) One bargaining strategy available to organized public employee groups is to target unused surplus funds as a financial source for the award of pay concessions. Since labor organizations have a vested interest in protecting the job security of their respective memberships, they 43 would be expected to View favorably the commitment of a dollar to pay personnel over the commitment of a dollar to cover the wide cadre of Operating expenses such as supplies, materials, equipment, utility services, etc. The greater the portion of the budget which is used to support these Operating needs, the greater also should be the determination among the union leadership and membership to obtain the concessions sought. An accurate accounting of the availability of these funds would require extensive examination of the audit statements of each jurisdiction taking a strike. Although this is beyond the sc0pe of this study, one proxy is available--the prOportion of total revenues which are not consumed by direct personnel costs (SL). SL = (RV - PE) / RV Where: RV = total revenues received by the jurisdiction taking the strike during the fiscal year 1975; RE = total expenditures for personnel during the fiscal year 1975. In one sense, SL is a crude measure for the availability of excess funds which might conceivably be 44 used to justify concessions. It does nevertheless represent, to a limited degree, the extent to which labor could be eXpected to know if the employer does (or does not) have the ability to make concessions. The greater is SL, the greater the tension one would expect between labor and management, especially since a strike has occurred. In effect, there is a larger share of the pie to fight over, even though management may have already committed the bulk of these funds to support non-personnel expenses or possibly capital expansion programs. This suggests there should be longer strikes. It remains unclear, however, whether an employer might be willing to concede earlier. The Sign on SL, as with other variables in the Ci vector, thus remains indeterminant. t Local Tax Burden (TB) The extent to which local citizens must bear the costs of government Should be a factor in determining the length of a strike. The greater the local tax burden relative to the services received, the greater should be the degree of community resistance toward awarding concessions to public employees which have elected to strike. This represents a constraint to the extent that additional concessions can be financed only through increased tax assessments. If the strikers respond to public pressure, shorter strikes would be expected. It is also conceivable that the local tax burden 45 and lack of community support for an additional tax assess- ment reduces the employer's willingness to make concessions. A high tax burden, relatively Speaking, should become a formidable obstacle for an employer interested in identifying the source of future revenues. Under these circumstances, TB would be positively associated with strike duration. Little is known about labor's response across various strike situations to financial constraints faced by the employer. Accordingly, the eXpectation for TB, a variable constructed to measure the local tax burden, is indetermi- nant. This variable is an index which is composed of two variables: TB (PT / PE) + (PT / RV) Where: PT = total property taxes paid by local citizens (including businesses) during fiscal year 1975; PE total expenditures for personnel, 1975; RV = total revenues reviewed by the jurisdiction from all sources during fiscal year 1975. The first component of this index, PT/PE, captures 46 the extent to which voters perceive a return in terms of the delivery of government services relative to their tax contributions. The second component of the TB index, PT/RV, captures the extent to which local taxes support government services relative to the revenues received from other governmental sources. The Bargaining Relationship The Bit Vector Researchers have been interested for many years in examining the relationship between the size of the work group and strike prOpensity.25 Regardless of the terminology (plant size, firm size, size of community or Size of work group), it has been hypothesized that small work units are less dehumanizing than large units.26 Given the greater degree of informality and personalization associated with small work groups, acceptable settlements Should be easier to identify. Number of Employees Involved in the Strike (SZ) Previous work on strikes has, as noted in Chapter 2, been oriented toward the macro level of analysis. This explains why measures of work group size have been so indirect. Burton and Krider used, as a proxy, a variable which measured the level of urbanization in their cross section strike study.27 Average firm size and average 47 plant size in an industry have been used in a recent study of strikes in private sector employment.28 This study considers a more direct measure, the number of employees who were involved in the strike (SZ). In using size, the breadth of the strike (one of the three dependent measures often used in strike studies) is taken as a positive predictor of duration. Combined Occupational Composition of the Bargaining Unit (CM) Labor organizations of course do not necessarily speak with a unified voice at the bargaining table. When units are composed of diverse occupational groups, highly diversified needs can exist with respect to work rules, job security and equity in pay. As an "unstable amalgam of interests," one WOUld expect that longer periods of time might be required to discuss, and subsequently to resolve these differences. More homogenous units, with clearly formulated demands, should be able to engage in a unified negotiation strategy which is credible and convincing. An employer, recognizing that there is little dissension among the membership over what constitutes an acceptable settlement, may "give in" more readily to demands than when competing interests must be served.29 The existence of combined, heterogeneous, units (CM) should thus be positively associated with duration. 48 It is also reasonable to believe that the duration of the strike is related to the employee type involved. Justifications for why some employee groups would be eXpected to have longer strikes relative to other groups, and why others might be expected to have shorter strikes, are discussed below. Firefighter Strikes (FIR) From a public policy point of view, considerable importance has been attributed to maintaining uninterrupted firefighting services. Replacement of firefighters is particularly difficult, however, in view of the SOphisticated nature of modern fighting equipment. Neither the state police nor the national guard are, as a general rule, proficient in using this equipment. Firefighters have also long been recognized as one employee type which places a premium on maintaining a reservoir of good will in their respective communities.30 Long and perhaps bitter strikes could easily jeOpardize this good will. A dummy variable set equal to 1 if the strike was by firefighters, (FIR), should thus have a negative sign. Police (POL) Police also provide a service which is considered essential. When police strike, the safety and civil order of a community is jeOpardized. This should exert pressure on employers to make necessary concessions and on the 49 police to return to work earlier than otherwise might have been the case. On the other hand, because of the increased threat to the safety of the community, employers may be more willing to search for and to acquire the temporary services of a trained civil defense unit (public or private). Interest in maintaining order in the community, regardless of the added cost involved, would be heightened. Once replacements are obtained, the pressure on employers to obtain an early settlement is mitigated. In consideration of the countervailing effect of these factors, the Sign on POL, a dummy variable set equal to 1 if the strike was by poli c e , i s indeterminant . Sani tation Strikes (SAN) Sanitation strikes (SAN) could also be inversely related to duration, but for a different reason. Inherent in the type of service delivered by sanitation workers is a Continuous impact on an entire community. When solid WaSte is not picked up as scheduled, it begins to collect On Street curbs. Garbage disposal units begin to overflow, resulting in a threat to the health of citizens. When waste water treatment plant workers strike, sewerage can be held in holding tanks for only a few days before it begins to back flow into businesses and homes. Pressure from citizens, directed at both the employer and the sanitation worker, would be expected to mount rapidly. The net result may be 50 a threat to subcontract services with a private sanitation firm, especially if the employer thinks the union's demands are unreasonable. This would suggest that the sign on SAN should be negative. On the other hand, empirical evidence exists which Shows a positive Sign on SAN.31 This may be because San i tat ion workers , for the reasons discussed above, have enhanced bargaining power. Further, since there is a high prOportion of sanitation workers in private employment, the counterpart public employment worker may be more prone to emulate the type of militant behavior found in private employment. On balance, this reasoning, coupled with the finding of a positive relationship in prior studies, suggests an exPectation of a positive Sign on SAN. Health Care Workers (HOS) In a study comparing the attitudinal militancy of nurses and teachers, Alutto and Belasco found that nurses, as a group, are more disposed toward militancy than teachers. This finding is not altered when they control for sex across the two groups.32 Therefore, the duration of strikes by nurses and other health care workers (HOS) is expected to be longer than strikes initiated by teachers. Controls for three other employee groups will also be considered. No empirical or theoretical basis exists, however, for making predictions. These are strikes by street and highway workers (STR) , transportation 51 anployees (TRN) and welfare service workers (WEL). Post hoc interpretations over the meaning of the signs found on the coefficients for these dummy variables are also subject to considerable qualification due to the small number of strike occurrences for these groups. Other Employee Types (0TH) Other bargaining units which initiated a strike comprise a variety of employee type combinations. In one case, firefighters and police may have been combined into the same unit. In another, sanitation workers may be combined with street and highways workers. The OTH category thus represents for many cases, the existence of a mixed occupational bargaining unit. Its correlation with CM should be strong. As was the case with CM, the Sign on OTH, a dummy variable set equal to l for strikes by all other employee groups except education, should thus be positive. Degree of Inessentiality (NS) While it is important to control for unique factors which characterize the various employee groups, it is also meaningful to consider the degree of essentiality commonly associated with the services delivered by the various employee groups. The greater the degree of essentiality, the greater should be the pressure for a timely strike settlement, other things being equal. Previous 52 research on the empirical relationship between strike duration and the degree of essentiality confirms this belief, although no attempt was made in these studies to control for other factors which should also affect duration.33 In this study, public employee services were categorized into three basic types: (1) Essential services - police and firefighters; (2) Intermediate services - sanitation, hospitals, transit, water and sewerage; (3) Nonessential - streets, parks, education, housing, welfare and general administration. An index of inessentiality (NS) has thus been constructed which represents varying degrees of essentiality. The number 1 is assigned if the striking employee group is either the police or firefighters, the number 2 is assigned if the employee group falls within the intermediate services category, and the number 3 is assigned if the strike is initiated by one of the nonessential employee types. Since the most essential employee groups are assigned the smallest number, NS is expected to be positively associated with duration. 53 The variables 82, FIR, POL, SAN, OTH, HOS, STR, TRN, WEL, NS and CM constitute the bargaining relationship vector Bi and thereby represent an importance facet of t the overall labor relations environment. A consideration of the bargaining context, another important aspect of the labor relations environment, is also important. The Bargaining Environment The Pit Vector Negotiation of the First Agreement (FN) Once a policy is in effect and a determination of the bargaining unit has been made, the parties are obligated to negotiate. Negotiation of first contracts, however, may be most difficult. Strikes occurring after recognition, but before a written contract has been obtained, may be long and bitter. The union tends to get "shunted around among the conflicting or overlapping authorities of a department manager, a mayor and a city council."34 Observers of the problems associated with the negotiation (n5 first contracts have suggested that the parties, inexperienced often in the give and take of the collective bargaining process, are less inclined to alter their original positions, eSpeCially after a strike has been initiated.35 Further, no contract language exists over which the parties can haggle. In view of the disagree- ments which can arise, especially after a bitter recognition 54 campaign, considerable time should be required, even after the strike has begun, to settle on acceptable contract language. FN, a dummy variable representing the negotiation of a first contract, should thus be positively related to duration. Union Support for the Work StOppage (US) Without the support of the labor organization there is no formal mechanism through which worker grievances can be heard. Strikes initiated without the support of the bargaining agent would indeed be expected to be short lived - The membership resPonsible for an unauthorized strike would not be eligible for strike benefits, if any eXiSt-36 Also, depending on the union constitution which 9'0Verns relationships between the international union and its member locals, unauthorized strike action may be grounds for establishing trusteeship. Thus, the Sign on US: a variable representing the presence of union support for the strike, Should be positive. The Issues Under DiSpute Although a majority of strikes in public employ- mer11: result from disputes over economic issues, this is not tr‘l‘e of all strikes. One-fourth of the strikes which OcczlJarred during the negotiation or renegotiation of a co I‘1‘t3li‘act during 1977 and 1978 were for non-economic 55 reasons.37 Other concerns important to striking employees include job security, the administration of work rules, promotions and demotions, and the administration of the contract. No empirical evidence is available on whether economic strikes in public employment are longer or shorter, certeris paribus, than the non-economic strike. Recent evidence, however, suggests that strikes over economic issues in private sector employment are longer. Economic issues, in a 196738 study, were defined to include general wage changes, supplementary benefits (pensions, insurance, dismissal pay, premium pay) and adjustments to the rate of pay due to such considerations as job reclassification, incentive rate adjustments, or changes in policy pertaining to retroactivity of wage adjustments. One plausible expla- n"MT-ion is that non-economic issues were less important to the membership. For this reason, workers were less willing to Sustain a long strike. This evidence, although not dj~11‘ectly relevant to the public employment situation, suggests strikes over economic issues may, as a general rule, be POSitively associated with duration. In contrast with the approach taken in the 1967 Strike study, two types of economic issues will be considered in this analysis--those which resulted primarily over wages (EC) and those which resulted primarily over a 39 c orl<=earn with supplemental or fringe benefits (SB). 3 . upplemental benefits were considered to be: (1) penSlonSr 56 insurance, or other welfare programs, (2) severance or dismissal pay such as Supplemental Unemployment Benefits (SUB) or the Guaranteed Annual Wage (GAW), (3) premium pay (shifts, overtime or weekend pay), (4) travel time, vacation pay, paid holidays, lunch periods, call in pay, Sick leave, vacation allowances, funeral leave. Because only 16 strikes out of the 558 cases occurred because of one of the issues noted above, any conclusions with respect to the performance of this variable should be considered very preliminary. The coefficients on both EC and SB are expected to be positive. The existence of a positive relationship may, in part, depend on the financial ability of the employer to "give in" to demands. In jurisdictions which are hard pressed to identify sufficient revenues to meet current expenditures, job security issues may be more important bargaining issues than wages or fringe benefits. It is important to take into account different economic milieu, especially when economic issues are the principal issue. The interaction terms EC*WB and EC*SL will thus also be considered as a relevant factor. The four variables (FN, US, EC and SB) represent the bargaining environment of unit i during time period t. These variables constitute vector Pit' Other factors merit consideration which cannot be directly associated with any of the vectors discussed above. These are the season and location of the strike. 57 fiflnese two general factors have been identified in prior rwesearch as relevant considerations and are therefore irucluded in the control vector Kit’ Additional Considerations: Where and When The K. Vector st Location There is a considerable body of research by suaciologists which has examined the impact on strikes of . . . . 40 . \nar1ous commun1ty character1st1cs. In a recent analys1s (IE private sector strikes, this trend was expanded to ichlude a prediction of strike occurrences across Standard DuetrOpolitan Statistical Areas (SMSA's). This research was iJlspired by Kerr and Siegel's suggestion in the 1950's that strikes are associated with the extent to which a community is tightly or loosely interconnected.4 In the urban, more congested, less personalized environments, longer strikes are expected. As suggested forty years ago: "A society where farmers predominate is likely to require industrial employees and employers to co-Operate."42 The Sign on RU, a dummy variable coded as a 1 if the strike occurred outside of an SMSA, is therefore expected to be negative. This relationship should be strengthened by the fact the RU is also likely to be an inverse proxy for union 58 penetration. Region of the strike should also be relevant. Strikes which occur in the northern states, where public employee collective bargaining has stronger political support, would be expected to be longer than strikes occurring in the western or southern regions of the country. The coefficient on NO should thus be positive. Strikes in southern states, on the other hand, Should be shorter relative to the length of strikes in the west or the north. Collective bargaining is not well established, nor has it been enthusiastically accepted in southern states. Season Skeels hypothesized that strikes during the winter months should be shorter, other considerations held constant, than strikes occurring during the summer months.43 Using a dummy variable to represent three of the four seasons of the year, he finds that, controlling for economic and political factors, strikes occurring in the winter lasted significantly fewer days than strikes occurring in the fall. With winter strikes, there is less Opportunity to picket or otherwise solicit public support. Since this reasoning would not be expected to apply to strikes occurring in southern or western states, the interaction term NO*WR (where WR represents a strike occurring during f‘ (3. :1 ('14 K); f1 Cc 59 the winter months (December, January and February) is expected to be inversely related to duration. The Public Policy Vector (Lit) The final vector, is comprised of two Lit' dispute resolution procedures which are used to resolve public employee diSputes (mediation and the court injunction), and one public policy found in state laws covering local government employees, the permissive strike law. Considered first is the relationship of the two impasse resolution mechanisms on strike duration. Over the past decade, penalities have been imposed on workers and on labor organizations who struck, cease and desist injunctions have been issued by the courts, and mediators have participated in the resolution of many disputes. These procedures have been supported and guided by a variety of state and local laws.44 In some states, disputes that remain unsettled after the termination of the contract must be mediated by third parties who are employed by the state's public sector labor relations commission. Other states encourage the mediation of disputes by neutrals from the private sector or from the Federal Mediation and Conciliation Service (FMCS). As an alternative remedy, the judiciary can be requested by an employer to issue an 60 injunction when a strike threatens the health and safety of a community. The penalty, a more punitive measure than a cease and desist order, is also imposed occasionally on striking employees or on their respective labor organizations. The Court Injunction (IJ) Historically, most public policies have supported the involvement of the courts in public employee disputes.45 These policies evolved because the threat of an injunction was thought to be instrumental in preventing strike occurrences.46 To be a credible threat, however, the injunction must also be effective in convincing workers who illegally strike to return to work. The injunction could, however, aggravate militancy. One observer has suggested that "a ban on strike is, in itself, an inducement to strike."47 When employees refuse to comply with an injunction, the petitioner is placed in the tenuous position of choosing among several unattractive courses of action, including further litigation. In most states, courts have the latitude of imposing penalties on the members or the union that struck when an injunction is deliberately disobeyed. Whether threats, coercion, dismissal or some combination thereof constitute the nature of the action taken, employees may actually become more uncompro- mising. Compromise, after all, is critical to obtaining a settlement. The net effect of IJ, a dummy variable repre- senting the issuance of a court injunction, is thus 61 indeterminant. Mediation (ME) Unlike the court injunction, mediation is an impasse procedure which is widely practiced.49 It is popular because of the anticipation that a better mutual understanding will result over the substantive issues in dispute. The suggestion of compromises by a mediator also introduces a new dimension to the bargaining process. The parties are no longer merely reacting to the same prOposalS and counter- prOposalS. With an outside prOposal on the table, the parties, it is assumed, are more likely to settle. Mediators thus introduce a sense of law and order to the bargaining process. Skilled third parties can also help inexperienced negotiators avoid dysfunctional bargaining strategies which can contribute to a lengthening of a dispute. Earlier settlements should be facilitated. The sign on the coefficient of ME, a dummy variable which represents the presence or absence of mediation, should be negative. The prediction of a negative relationship for ME could, on the other hand, be counterbalanced by the assign- ment of mediators to strikes which are unusually difficult to settle. The extent to which this effect may (or may not) be present is the subject of Chapter 5. Permissive Strike Law (PL) Nine states have enacted permissive public sector 62 strike laws. Seven of these states experienced at least one strike during the 1977-1978 period of this analysis. In Montana, only strikes by firefighters are prohibited. In Oregon, all public employees except police, firefighters and guards at prisons and hospitals have a right to strike as long as all pre-strike procedures prescribed by statute have been met. Pennsylvania, with a law similar to Oregon's, also prohibits guards and court employees from striking. In Vermont, non-teaching municipal employees may strike if 30 days have passed since the issuance of a fact finder's report and the dispute has not been submitted to an arbitrator. Minnesota porvides a limited right to strike to all non-essential employee groups. In Alaska, only "semi essential" personnel (utility, school, snow removal and sanitation workers) may strike. In no state is the strike privilege extended to all public employee groups and in no state is this right totally unqualified. Without mandatory legal sanctions against strikes the courts can not be employed as a mechanism for forcing workers to return to work. The presence of these laws also represents public support of and tolerance for strikes by public employees. The dummy variable PL measures the existence of a permissive strike law in a state's collective bargaining policy. It should be positively associated with strike duration. 63 The Expanded Estimating Model The expanded form of the estimating model to be used in this study is as follows: (1) S. = f(E. it Where: S. rt it it it it it B L.) C it’ it P K tt' it’ it’ it’ represents the number of working days lost as a result of a strike in bargaining unit i during time period t; is a vector of variables representing the expectations of bar- gaining unit i employees during time period t; is a vector of variables which measure: the- economic and political constraints on the bargaining unit i employer during time period t; is a vector of variables representing the structure of bargaining unit i during time period t; denotes a vector of variables which describe the bargaining environment of unit i during time period t: denotes a vector of control variables which are expected to affect the duration of the strike by bargaining 64 unit i employees during time period t; Lit is a vector of policy variables expected to affect the strike initiated by bargaining unit i during time period t. Having discussed and defined the variables to be considered in this study, the results from entering these variables in a multiple regression are presented in Chapter 4. As a prelimary to this discussion, the method and unit of analysis will be reviewed. 65 Footnotes (Chapter 3) Robert A. McLean, "Coalition Bargaining and Strike Acitivty in the Electrical Equipment Industry, 1950-1974," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 30, No. 3 (April, 1977), p. 360. Orley Ashenfelter & George Johnson, "Bargaining Theory Trade Unions, and Industrial Strike Activity," Egg American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 1 (March, 1969), pp. 35-49. The prOposition that strikes are not economically profitable to the union membership is not undisputed, however. In an analysis of 26 strikes in the Vancouver area of Canada, strikes were found to be profitable to the union membership, even after conservative assumptions about the probability of continued employment and the availability of alternative job Opportunities during the strike were made. See B. Curtis Eaton, "The Worker and the Profitability of the Strike," Industrial & Labor Relations Review, Vol. 26, No. 1, (October, 1972), PP. 670—679. For a critical discussion of the Ashenfelter and Johnson analysis, see P. K. Edwards, "Time Series Regression Models of Strike Activity: A Reconsideration with American Data," British Journal of Industrial Relations V01. 16, No. 3 (November, 1978), p. 320. AS further noted by one critic, this model "fails to take into account that the executive ... must have some degree of confidence in order to negotiate with employers at all." Otherwise, the union leadership will "lose all credibility as a negotiating instrument with management." There is no strong evidence, however, that there has been a dissipation in the credibility of the union leadership at the negotiating table. Malcolm Fisher, op. cit., p. 80. John C. Anderson & Thomas A. Kochan, "Impasse Procedures in the Canadian Federal Service: Effects on the Bargaining Process," Industrial & Labor Relations Review, Vol. 30, No. 3 (April, 1977), p. 288. 6 This was initially demonstrated by the insignificance of a variable used to measure industry profits in the Ashenfelter and Johnson study, Op. cit. 66 This framework was originally used in an analysis of private sector strike activity, with no assertion that it was applicable, necessarily, to analyses of public employee strike activity. In a review of over 50 newspaper accounts of strikes in the public sector which occurred during 1975, it was found that in more than one- fourth of the cases, settlements were reached sometime after the workers returned to the jobs. For a further discussion of this issue, see Thomas A. Kochan, "Dynamics of Dispute Resolution in the Public Sector," in Benjamin Aaron, Joseph Grodin and James Stern, Public Sector Bar ainin (Washington, D. C.: Bureau of National Affairs, I979), p. 168. 8 This terminology is borrowed from Neil Chamberlain & James W. Kuhn, Collective Bargaining (New York: McGraw Hill, 1965). pp. 170-173. 9 For a summary of recent studies of strike duration which build on the work by Ashenfelter and Johnson, see Robert Stern, Op. cit., p. 34. 10 This has been described as a form of aspirational deprivation, in contrast with decremental or progressive deprivation. Korpi warns that increasing aspirational deprivation should be positively, but not necessarily Significantly related to the probability of conflict. Walter Korpi, "Conflict, Power and Relative Deprivation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 68 (1974), pp. 1575-1576. 11 T. R. Gurr, "A Comparative Study of Civil Strife," in H. D. Graham & T. R. Gurr (eds.), Violence in America (New York: New American Library), p. 590. 12 This idea has been identified in the literature as the orbits of coercive comparison. See Neil W. Chamberlain & James W. Kuhn, Collective Bargaining (New York: McGraw- Hill, 1965). pp. 2034209. These standards are Similar to the criteria applied by arbitrators. See Frank Elkouri & Edna Elkouri, How Arbitration Works (Washington, D. C.: BNA, 1973): pp. 745-796; Howard S. BIOck, "Criteria in Public Sector Interest Disputes," Proceedings of the 24th Meeting of the National Academy of Arbitrators (Washington, -— D. C.: BNA, 1971) 67 13 Charles Perry, "Teacher Bargaining: The EXperience in Nine Systems," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, V01. 33, No. 1 (October, 1979), pp. 10-11. 14 Robert N. Stern, "Methodological Issues in Quantitative Strike Analysis," Industrial Relations, Vol. 17, No. 1 February, 1978), p. 38. 15 This was also the conclusion of a summary of recent work in the area of public policy and labor relations research. Ralf R. Jones, Public Sector Labor Relations: An Evaluation of Poligy Related Research (Contract Research Corporation, 19751, p. 53. 16 For the construction of different wage change measures, see Jack W. Skeels, "Measures of U.S. Strike Activity," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 24, No.4 (July, 1971), pp. 515-525; David Snyder, "Early North American Strikes: A Reinterpretation," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 30, No. 3 (April, 1977). 17 These dates are an artifact of the fact that the Annual Survey of Governments, from which these measures are drawn, is conducted on October 15th of each year. For a further eXplanation of the sources for the variables to be used in this analysis, see Appendix A. 18 This same variable has, however, been Operationalized in an entirely different manner. David Snyder, Op. cit., used a moving average of the rate of change in wages over a Six year period of time to represent the divergence (or convergence) of expectations. The possibility of constructing a wage comparison measure such as CE has not been possible in previous studies because the bargaining unit initiating the strike was not the primary unit of analysis. The conception of an expectations variable is not a new idea. Operationalization of this variable in this study is, however, a refinement on earlier strike research. 19 This concept was first introduced by Alfred Marshall in Principles of Economics, 8th edition (New York: Macmillan Company, 1949), pp. 383-387; see also Albert Rees, The Economics of Trade Unions (Chicago: The UniversityTOf ChICago Press, I960), pp. 70-73. 68 20 Malcolm Fisher, Op. cit., p. 81. 21 Samuel P. Hayes, "Psychology of Conciliation and Arbitration," in George W. Hartmann & Theodore Newcomb (eds.), Industrial Conflict (New York: The Gordon Company, 1939) p. 417. 22 A measure of labor costs to total costs has traditionally been viewed as the prOportion of all labor costs of the firm to total costs. The WB measure thus differs from this construction. It has been modified primarily because public, rather than private sector strikes are being studied. 23 For a discussion of the implications to a public employer of granting particularly generous concessions to one employee group, see Roben W. Fleming, "Public Employee Bargaining--Problems and PrOSpects," Industrial Relations Research Association (1978), pp. 14-23. 24 As public employee bargaining has matured over the past decade, the parties have undoubtedly become more SOphisticated in their negotiation strategies. Some public employee labor organizations have develOped elaborate auditing procedures for identifying the extent to which a public employer has the ability to grant the concessions demanded. The Michigan Education Association, for example, has develOped a computer program which analyzes public expenditures in comparison to revenues. Nevertheless, the identifying of financial reserves to pay concessions, eSpecially in the larger jurisdictions, is a practical impossibility. The availability of uncommited, surplus reserves can be skillfully hidden by public employers through the establishment of special accounts for utilities, the commitment of funds to capital expansion prOgrams which have not been approved by the governing body, or the refusal to report surplus funds carried over from one fiscal year to the next. The variable SL may better represent, then, the extent to which the union membership believes there "is enough in the kitty" to grant the concessions sought, than the extent to which funds may, in fact, be available for this purpose. As such, it could be viewed as a candidate for the Eit vector. 69 25 For one of the earliest studies, see Sherill Cleland, Influences of Plant Size on Industrial Relations (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1955). 26 John Shorey, "The Size of the Work Unit and Strike Incidence," Journal of Industrial Economy (1977), Vol. 23, No. 2, p. 177. 27 Burton and Krider, op. cit., pp. 156-157. 28 Robert N. Stern, "Toward and Empirical Merger: Sociological Conceptions of Strike Activity," 28th Annual Meeting of the Industrial Relations Research Association Proceeding§7(l975), pp. 59—61. 29 Malcolm Fisher, Op. cit., p. 28. 30 James A. Craft, "Fire Fighter Strategy in Wage Negotiations," Quaterly Review of Economics and Business, Vol. 11, 31 Burton and Krider, Op. cit., p. 171. 32 Joseph A. Alutto & James A. Belasco, "Determinants of Attitudinal Militancy Among Nurses and Teachers," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 27, No. 2 (January, 1974), pp. 220-222. 33 John F. Burton and Charles Krider, "The Role and Consequences of Strikes by Public Employees, in J. Joseph Loewenberg and Michael H. Moskow (eds.), Collective lgargaining in Government (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: l?rentice Hall, 1972), pp. 278-279. 34 'Neil W. Chamberlain, "Public vs. Private Sector Bargaining," in Loewenberg and Moskow, Op. cit., p. 16. 35 Albert A. Blum and Gadi Harel, "The Generic Reasons for Strikes: An Interpretative Analysis of the Israeli Case," unpublished manuscript, 1978. 70 36 Sheldon M. Kline, "Strike Benefits of National Unions," Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 98, No. 3 (March, 1975), pp. T7-23. 37 This was drawn from preliminary analyses of the machine readable data file obtained from the BLS which covered the years 1975-1978. 38 David B. Lipsky and Henry S. Farber, "The Composition of Strike Activity in the Construction Industry," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 3 (April,l976), pp. 388-404. 39 Stern has recently addressed the importance of considering models which take into consideration different issues over which strikes occur. See Robert N. Stern, "Quantitative Strike Analysis, op. cit., p. 41. 40 James R. Lincoln, "Community Structure and Industrial Conflict: An Analysis of Strike Activity in SMSA'S," American Sociological Review, Vol. 43 (April, 1978), pp. 199-220. 41 Clark Kerr and Abraham Siegel, "The Interindustry PrOpensity to Strike," in Arthur Kornhauser, Robert Dubin, and A. Ross (eds.), Industrial Conflict (New York, 1954). 42 Samuel Hayes, "Psychology of Conciliation and Arbitration," in George Hartman and Theodore Newcomb (eds.), Industrial Conflict (New York: Gordon Company, 1939), p. 410. 43 Jack Skeels, "Measures of U.S. Strike Activity," op. cit. For a much earlier discussion, see Dale Yoker No. 4 (July, 1971), pp. 515-525; see also Dale Yoker, "Seasonality in Strikes," Journal of the American Statistical Association, V61. 33, No. 204 (December, 1938). pp. 687-693. 71 44 The most recent summary of these policies can be found in U.S. Department of Labor, Labor Management Services Administration, Summary of Public Sector Labor Relations Policies: Statutes, Attorney General's Opinions and Selected Court DeciSions (Washington, D. C.: GPO, 1979). 45 A recent summary of penalty laws found across the 50 states is available in the Hawaii Labor Relations Group, Guide to Statutory_Provisions in Public Sector Colipctive Bargaining, "Strike Rights and Prohibitions,"’(Industrial Relations Center, University of Hawaii, 1978). According to John Bonner, Director of the Office of Public Labor Relations, Department of Labor, there are considerable differences across states in the extent to which penalties are legally used to shorten the duration of strikes. 46 An excellent summary of the pros and cons of strike penalties can be found in Eva Robbins, "Penalties in Strikes Against a Public Employer, the New York 'COnference Series, Vol. 22, pp. 315-335. 47 William J. Kilberg, "A LImited Right to Strike for Public Employees," in Loewenberg and Moskow, Op. cit., p. 306; An alternative view has been offered by Paul Gerhart. Finding that strike penalties, with explicit prescriptions for the type of penalty to be imposed, were inversely and Significantly related to outcomes, Gerhart suggests that it is not whether strikes are prohibited, but "whether penalties for engaging in strikes are explicit." Paul F. Gerhart, "Determinants of Bargaining Outcomes in Local Government Labor Negotiations," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 3 (April, 1976), p. 344. 48 The Department of Labor has recently funded a study examining the impact of penalties on strike activity, with particular emphasis on whether they reduce the occurrence of duration of the strike. 49 For a discussion of the function of impasse procedures, see Anthony V. SinicrOpi, Dispute Settlement in the gpblic Sector: The State of the Art (Washington, D.C.: GPO, 1972) “1.5 . o . r0 H (D rn rn Chapter 4 The Analysis This chapter is composed of two sections. The first discusses the method of analysis and the data. Results are presented and analyzed in the second section. The Method of Analysis and the Data The unit of analysis to be used is the local government bargaining unit (or units) which was involved in a work stOppage while negotiating or renegotiating a collec- tive bargaining contract.1 Strikes by state government employees were excluded because of the difficulty in ascertaining the composition and SCOpe of the bargaining unit at the state level.2 The analysis will include strikes which occurred in the United States between January 1, 1977 and October 15, 1978. During this period, 558 stOppages, resulting in 5,108 days of idleness, satisfy this description.3 Data on the characteristics of stOppages are available from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). Strikes are identified through newspaper accounts which are monitored on a daily basis by the BLS district offices, and the Federal Mediation and Conciliation Service. Because short strikes may not be as newsworthy, the data represent a biased representation of the larger strikes. 72 'LJ 73 Requests for information are then sent to the public employer and to the employee association (or union) involved. In approximately 33% of all instances, responses are received from both parties. The bulk of the other responses come from public management. BLS officials estimate that between 95% and 98% of all public employee strikes are included in this file. The information requested on the BLS Work StOppage Report includes a report on when and how long the strike lasted,4 the type of employee group involved, the union, and the types of dispute resolution procedures which were used, if any, to resolve the impasse. Data is also requested on whether the strike occurred during the first or a subsequent negotiation period. These responses, in conjunction with what is known about the strike from press reports, are coded onto machine readable data files. This data was acquired with the support of a National Association of Schools of Public Affairs and Administration/National Association of Counties dissertation fellowship. While this data file identifies the union involved, the jurisdiction involved remains anonymous. Fortunately, the Bureau of the Census uses BLS strike reports to identify the jurisdiction affected. Considerable effort is taken to insure that the correct jurisdiction is identified. If it iS not clear on the BLS Work StOppage Report which juris- diction took the strike, a phone call (or calls) are made to 13‘ jl t} t at 74 insure that an accurate determination is made. The case number assigned by the BLS, unfortunately, has no correspondence with the jurisdiction ID number assigned by the Census. Thus, the extensive data resources collected by these two agencies could only be merged by obtaining a lexicon which matched the BLS case number with the Census jurisdiction ID number. It was learned that the jurisdiction identification number was written on a COpy of the BLS strike questionnaire which was used by the Census to develOp their internal strike files. The Census provided a listing of the BLS case number with their matched juris- diction ID numbers for all 1978 strikes. A Similar listing of 1977 strikes was gathered by the investigator during a field trip to Washington, D.C. in October, 1979. By merging the BLS strike files with the Census files on earnings and collective bargaining coverage, the union which initiated the strike could be associated with the jurisdiction which took the strike. Having identified the jurisdiction involved, Census data found on machine readable data files were matched with the data coded onto the BLS strike file. These data were drawn from the annual employment survey which was sent to all jurisdictions in the country during 1977, and to a sample of 15,000 jurisdictions during 1975 and 1976.5 This survey requests participating governments to report infor- mation on the monthly earnings by employee group as well as data on collective bargaining coverage. Finance data were (V) 75 also drawn from the 1975 Census finance machine readable data file. For the variables drawn from the Census data, RE, EV, WB, NU, SL, and TB (see Appendix A), the number of strikes in jurisdictions sampled by the Census equaled 412. For this reason, regression results reported in this chapter utilize samples of varying sizes, depending on the variables which are included in the regressions. Measures to be examined in this study are expected to be interrelated. It is reasonable to expect that the same factors which theoretically explain strike duration will also be related to each other. Introducing modified versions of the basic model permits the inclusion of highly correlated variables in separate equations. Their independ- ent effects on duration can then be evaluated. Reformulation of the basic model also permits deletion of variables found to be insignificant. The performance of significant predictors can then be reexamined. Moreover, an important purpose served by the consideration of multiple variables in Ei the expectations t! vector, and in Ci the constraints vector, is to enhance t’ the probability of identifying at least one (or more) variables for each general factor which contributes to an explanation of strike duration. The number of valid cases will vary depending on the variable in the regression having the fewest number of nonmissing values. Tests of significance are based on Ch th Th Ca Th de 8:1 an la fr. CO] 76 the number of observations for which all variables were found to have non-missing values. This is the sample size, or "n", which will be reported in the tables which follow. The Results The regressions reported in Tables 1 and 2 include as independent variables all of the factors identified in Chapter 3. The dependent variable, S is strike duration. it’ Two equations are reported in Table l. The first includes all "employee types" which were identified as components of vector Bi (FIR, POL, SAN, OTH, HOS, STR, t TRN, WEL). The omitted employee type reference category is education. As a variable which captures a common characteristic across the various employee groups, NS, the inessentiality index, is not entered in this equation. The essentiality of an employee group is sufficiently captured by the eight "employee type" dummy variables. The second equation considers the impact of NS, while deleting FIR, POL, SAN, OTH, HOS, STR, TRN, and WEL. CM, the combined bargaining unit variable, is not entered in the Table 1 equations because the construction and subsequent inclusion of WB, the labor cost to total labor cost variable, necessitated the identification of Specific employee groups. This, by definition, excluded from consideration employees who were organized into combined, or mixed bargaining units. Although constructed ...... ....3 Affirm.» :2..=..:.. 13:; .2 ac :t-fifiltt (J... . ......l NN. «o.l ma. no. #0.: ma.1 no.1 Ho. no.1 Ha. «H. «o.1 noon non NA.N ca en. es. Aeo.mc recon an Aen.c oao.r eo.r Ash.~c one. «N. as Aa~.c sea. Ho.r AeH.V mmo.r No.r “so.Hc ~oe.r eH.r a Aea.o nou.r ao.r Amo.o owe. so. Asa.c one.. no.- Aen.~o NAN. mo. Aoo.~c emu. SH. is Aen.v a-.r mo.r uaoaowuuooo moon acuuon no ~o>oa mo. ago on usaoauacqu needs «a Amo.av p sumac unuuop no Ho>oa oH. any as ucuoauacwua nudes a «H. coo. oxwuuu encode: nuaoauuuuooo any no road nova: A o manorucouua :« vouuoaou own nouoooru A~o.~v s odquuo Azxav couscous on eflsou unease uaauuueeunu nose on ooo.~ an eoeu>ue no: on. "mseoz me. .«oae. noeuuuuoeaeauu noN a Ao~.~c a «sane. seams ca. «no. accrue: on. uoouun ~n.~ a e «a Aen.~c + Amoco AN. we. Neo.n oxauuu Aqueous: N as «n. Ado.Hc + Assoc Hm. «Hun. «sauna woruo ch.~v + Adds Ana.fiv + andmv cease. nag ubuaauluoa we. «com. oxuuua cowuauuuoa Amo.c e Anus Aem.Hc a seems nNH.r coau0e5nnw me. «one. oxuuua nudged Aeo.nc r Auto Aeo.fic . «xenon» “memo . . . no a canon caduceus: no; «a ammo a u: an new “he.Hc + noose Away Aqo.o r Amzeozc nH.r mn~.i huaaaauaouaoua oHo.r nous“: e sauce Aon.c Aoa.c + Ammo Ao~.o r Aomv no. -o. #0. moo. and. as HoH.r ruse. .n Aco.~V + Aozv Ame.c Aoo.c a “mac aamn.r runes so. «no. we. «NH. nouns» uau Am~.Hc 1 Anne Ae~.fic Ase.c a Anny oo~.r anusu NH. one. no. con. luau. Aon.v r Ammo A-.v Ae~.c + Aszc «ma. Hausa: «a ~o.r noo.r «0.: noo.r canes .M An~.uc Amo.~c a . Anne Amo.Ho + Ammo mu. moo. we. «so. once nos-H osc.r apnea unmoaon «e «a «mo AoH.Ho + Aqua Aoq.~v Ann.av + A>uv hog. ozone one: OH. «ac. dc. “Ho. nouauuoaoo Hanuouaw Aeo.~c + Amos soo.c “Ne.c + Ammo ..nmo. oneness goes: so. nae. no. sea. Ho>ou «as: “-.v + Azmc Ano.Hc Aon.Hc + Amos csa.i coauawuouoc uauwm he no. nnH.H cu. mac.a unease aunt «a .m .u uaonuuuuooo omen o~pueu~> sauna» noon uaouonuuooo noon usuauquuooo (deem cap-«nus canoes oeuooaxu tenuous” mecca oupawuo> one moousoa uOu n xuucooa< mum Aoaeaum «He uses «a nounoauo> :oasu cascades: onerous .mv coauausv «sebum uo Souuowooua och van rue: A .H uqm<9 '7'7 78 differently from CM, OTH, the other, or catchall occupa- tional category, is a measure which also represents, to a large extent, the existence of combined units. Coefficients of multiple determination (R2=.27 and R2=.24) were generated for the two equations, respectively. This compares favorably with the explanatory power of the four year pooled regression for 1968-1971 obtained in the Burton-Krider study.6 In that study, an R2 of .10 was reported. The regressions also had F scores which were also significant at the 99% level of confidence. Note, however, that due to missing values for some of the variables, tests of significance were based on 205 and not 412 cases. While the expected signs on some of the coefficients were not predicted by the model, a number of variables were significant at the .05 level or better in at least one equation. These included coefficients on labor costs (WB), hospital strikes (HOS), transportation strikes (TRN), firefighter strikes (FIR), police strikes (POL), sanitation strikes (SAN), street and highway strikes (STR), other employee strikes (0TH), union support (US), northern strikes (NO) and mediation (ME). The signs found on FIR, NO and ME were not, however, predicted by the theoretical model develOped in Chapter 3. Perhaps most surprising was the finding of a coefficient on mediation (ME) which was positive and significant at the .01 level or better. There is no reason 79 to believe, based on this relationship alone, that mediation contributes to a lengthening of public employee strikes. In many cases, mediators may only become involved in the most militant strikes. In light of their importance from a public policy point of View, the performance of ME and the other Li variables will be analyzed in Chapter 5. t As observed, prior work on strikes has suggested that noneconomic considerations may be more important determinants of strike duration than economic factors. The three significant variables with unexpected signs-- firefighter strikes (FIR), north (NO), and mediation (ME)-- were all associated, however, with noneconomic vectors. Further, among the 22 variables considered in the bargain- ing vector (Bith the labor relations environment vector (Pit)' the legal vector (Lit) and the control vector (Cit)' less than half were significant in one or both of the regressions. Given the contradiction between the positive results for the variables in these vectors which were anticipated, and the discovery of many insignificant coefficients, it is apprOpriate to discuss first the P performance of the variables in vectors Bi and Ki t' it' t' The Bi Variables t In view of the relatively small number of strike occurrences for many of the employee groups (see Appendix B), the performance of the eight "employee type" variables 0‘ If V‘ . . me 9: St 80 needstx>be considered when using the 558 sample of cases. Note that because all variables (with the exception of CM) were included in Table 1, tests of Significance were based on a sample of 412 cases. The sample size was reduced as a result of merging the economic data drawn from the census data files. Two additional equations are thus reported in Table 2. Variables entered in this equation were drawn primarily from the BLS data source. The first considers the impact on duration, S of the "employee type" it' variables. This is illustrative, since the predictors which have strong correlations with the "employee type" variables were associated with the omitted Ci the political and tr economic constraints vector. The second regression considers the impact of NS, the inessentiality index, and CM. Tests of significance for the Table 2 regressions are based on 514 and 444 observations, respectively. Relative to the results for the 205 strike samples reported in Table 1, this narrows the interval required for predictors to be significant. The "employee type" control group is represented by instructional and noninstructional employees in education. A positive Sign on any of the eight "employee type" variables means that holding strikes by all other groups constant, this group experienced longer strikes relative to the length of strikes in education. Generally speaking, the evidence in Tables 1 and 2 81 suggests that strikes in education are not longer than strikes initiated by most other employee groups. For this to be true, the signs on the "employee type" variables should be negative. Instead, most signs are positive. The expectation that strikes in education Should be longer than strikes initiated by other, more essential "employee groups" such as firefighters or the police appears to merit reevaluation. Significant, positive coefficients were found in the equation seen in Table l for variables POL (police strikes), STR (street and highway strikes), HOS (hospital strikes), SAN (sanitation strikes), TRN (transportation strikes), FIR (firefighter strikes) and 0TH (strikes by other employee groups). Prior findings which supported the prediction of a positive Sign on HOS and SAN appear to be confirmed. According to these results, strikes by hospital workers are somewhat longer relative to strikes which occur in education. The Sign and significance for SAN is comparable in direction and significance to Burton and Krider's results.7 Conclusions based on these results alone must be considered tentative. Only 23 strikes among sanitation workers occurred during the period of this analysis, and a scant 8 strikes were found among hospital workers. Without the support of positive relationships in prior studies, one would be prone to conclude that these findings are, in and of themselves, inconclusive. oo. ea SN. oo. “-.no AN. «no. cc “so.o mo.r ooo.- Aoo.oo on. ore. cc Aeo.o No. omo. AoH.o oo.r omo.r Aoo.uo mo.r oen.- at Ann.oo oo.- Hoo.r Ao~.o No. goo. coco neoouuooooo «as o no.1 AN. Ho.r nH.r H dandy oom "mmhoz can aH.o as NN. no. Anm.no + Aqmv coo. 3oH o>woowauoa cc Aoo.o a Aouo owo.r aouuuaoncw Aoo.oo r Auto «coca cowuudvea «m A Aoo.o r Amneozo 0No.r Sauna: a sane: Ann.o r Aooo ono.i Susan ANo.NV + Aozo canon i sauce AnH.Ho r Aomo HAH.r Anus» Ann.o r Amso coo wound: no .M ucoaoauuuoo swam omboaun> neuuo> vouuoaxm coupon «one wooden venues or» long Spout nuapuauo> .mo cowuauav oxauuo up coauoavouo one wcqoanuxo car: A Awo.Ho mo.r oo~.r 1-.~o on. now. «a Aoo.~o N”. Hon. Cd. Aeo.o no.1 noH.r Aoo.No oo. ooo. Ga AaH.Ho oo.r soo.r “No.o no. ooo. Aon.~o no. onH.H Ao~.Ho no.1 soo.r xo~.~o oH. oNN. cc. Aoo.no no. oon. cc Aflh.o no.r moH.r Aoo.o so. ooo. AH~.o Ho.r nno.r Aoo.~o on. ono. c c AoH.o Ho.r Soo.r Aoo.Ho so. oon. Aoo.o No. ”so. AoN.o Ho. ooo. Aon.o Ho.- hko.r Aeo.o no. «No. .on.oo oo. oso. noon osooouooooo coco neouuoooooo Aueoaao ono .oso .N NAQ nouoo> €322 83 The only coefficient among the eight "employee type" variables which was Significant in both Table l and Table 2 was TRN (transportation strike). This was surprising, since an a priori prediction was not possible for this variable. With only 14 strikes in the sample, this finding could be a function of sampling error. It is interesting, however, that TRN is significant at the 99% level of confidence in both regressions. Bus drivers and other transit workers may be more inclined to wait longer for a settlement which compares favorably with the earnings obtained by their private sector counterparts. This finding may also be influenced by the impact of the New York City transit strikes during this period. It is interesting that the positive and Significant coefficients on FIR (firefighter strike), SAN (sanitation strike), POL (police strike), STR (street and highway strike) and OTH (other strike) became insignificant in Table 2. Signs on STR and POL were even negative. One possible explanation lies in the relationship seen between these variables and two of the variables associated with the Cit vector, SL (fiscal slack) and TB (the local tax burden index). The correlations between FIR, SAN, POL, OTH, STR and SL are positive and significant (r=.l7, r=.20, r=.ll, r=.40, and r=.l9 respectively). On the other hand, correlations between these variables and TB are negative (r=-.23, r=-.08, r=-.07, r=-.1l, and r=.02) and, in many cases, significant. In D—l 84 Since many of the "employee type" variables are inversely correlated with TB, the omission of TB from the Table 2 regressions means that these variables are probably picking up some of its variation. Thus, the positive association between "employee type" variables and strike duration is probably being reduced when TB is excluded. Note that the strong positive correlations between the "employee type" variables and Slack (SL) also infers that there is a strong negative correlation between the omitted "employee type" variable (education strikes) and SL. This correlation was r=-.7l. One inference that can be drawn from this is that noneducation public employees may have' an incentive to target strike actions against employers which have a greater capacity to make concessions. If the strike decision is a rationally determined process, then one would expect to see local labor organizations strike jurisdictions which extract a relatively low level of local taxes versus total revenues, and who have a relatively high degree of "slack." As discussed in Chapter 3, the SL variable (the prOportion of personnel expenditures as a component of total revenues received) is the variable in this study which most closely proxies the employer's ability to pay. The relatively strong association between the slack measure and the noneducation employee type variables may be partly explained by the fact that noneducation union locals take relatively independent action with respect to the (A; (I) ‘11 III In 85 decision to strike. The National Education Association (NBA), the sponsor of the largest number of public employee strikes during this period (256 out of 558), on the other hand, has conducted a more centrally coordinated bargaining strategy. In states such as Michigan, the NEA establishes a contract pattern that is used as a standard against which to evaluate the progress of negotiations with all school districts. Districts with a greater capacity to make concessions, with a higher degree of Slack (SL) and a lower tax burden (TB), are more likely to settle before strike action is necessary. Districts with relatively less capacity to make concessions (or having less slack and a higher tax burden) may thus be more likely to have strikes. An alternative explanation for the strong relation- ship between the "employee type" variables and both the slack and the tax burden variables is as follows: the prOportion of nonlabor costs to total revenues across all school districts which both take and avoid strikes is lower than for jurisdictions employing noneducation personnel. Further analysis, outside the scope of this study, would be necessary to verify this alternative explanation. The coefficient on WEL in Table l is positive, but not significant at the .10 level or better. Its sign in Table 2 is reversed. It also has a low beta weight (-.01). This seems to confirm the expectation of an ambiguous Sign on this variable. With only 13 welfare strikes (see 86 Appendix B), this finding is contaminated with considerable sampling error. In contrast to confirmatory findings for Signs on SAN, OTH, HOS and WEL, the negative sign on NS, the inessentiality index, was unexpected. Recall that less essential employee groups were assigned the higher number. A positive Sign had therefore been predicted for the NS variable. In the Table 1 results, NS also has a relatively large absolute beta (-.13) compared to the betas seen on other variables in this same equation. Findings for the "employee type" variables in the first regression are also consistent with this result, since strikes in education were categorized in Chapter 3 as the least essential employee group, NS=3. The construction of the dependent strike duration measure (Sit) was weighted in favor of the more essential employee groups (firefighters, police, and hospital workers) Since these groups provided services to the community on a continuous basis. The duration of the strike for these groups was defined as the calender duration of the strike. To a degree, this would have biased the finding of an inverse relationship between NS and Sit' The provision in many state laws for compulsory arbitration of firefighter and police strikes has apparently reduced their frequency. The negative Sign on NS suggests, however, that once firefighter and police strikes are initiated, there is no reason to believe that their duration C) U) r) :4 'Y1 (h In In K) 87 will necessarily be Shorter than strikes by teachers or other, less essential employee types. It is not unreasonable necessarily to find longer strikes among more essential employee groups. Employers would have a greater incentive to identify a readily available means of providing substitute services if an essential employee group has struck. Strike replacements, or even the enhanced credibility of the threat of hiring replacements, could lengthen a strike as labor and manage- ment become less amenable to compromise in the process. The performance of the Size variable (82) was positive, as predicted, but not significant. The failure of Size to influence strike duration significantly has also been found in four previous studies. Two of these studies constituted an examination of strikes in the private sector. The other two studies used non-education public employees as the unit of analysis. Britt and Galle found that the zero order correla- tion between strike extensivity (or duration) and average union size was not significant across eighteen broad industrial categories.8 This analysis included strikes in both manufacturing and nonmanufacturing industries. In an extension of this work, Stern found negative and insignifi- cant Signs on plant Size and average union size variables which were considered as predictors of strike duration.9 In their study of public employee strikes discussed in Chapter 2, Burton and Krider found that a proxy for work wk “w. B E nu; uri 9* 'r C. I NIL Cs F\ at 88 group Size, the percentage of employment in Cities over 50,000, was both negative and insignificant in a four year pooled regression for 1968-1971.10 In a replication of the Burton and Krider study that considered a more recent period (1974-1975), a negative and also insignificant sign was found on a size variable.ll IS Size really unrelated to strike duration? Since our hypothesis suggests there should be a relation- ship, it is possible that 82 is not linearly, but curvilinearly related. Because of their enhanced bargaining power, very large units may actually have shorter strikes. Certainly strike replacements would be difficult to recruit. One would also expect to find greater SOphisti- cation in the bargaining skills of both labor and manage- ment. A respecification of the basic model thus considers 2 SZ , in addition to 82, as predictors of Si These t' results are presented in two regressions found in Table 3. The first regression uses the same model specification as seen in Table l (the 412 sample). The second regression is Similar to the model specification used in the Table 2 regressions (the 558 sample). Since NS represents a common characteristic of all employee groups, it is entered in the Table 3 regressions in lieu of the eight "employee type" variables. This eliminates much of the multicolinearity among the predictors which was evident in the regressions reported in Table 1 and as evident in the correlation matrix reported as ANH.oo oN. ass. is AoN.o no.r noo.r ASN.oo me. one. a. Aoo.o Ho. oHo. AmN.o Ho.r moo.r ANN.No n~.r omn.r ca AoN.o no.r noo.r AoN.o No. ooo. noon uSOHuHuwooo oHanm can ask «N. «0.1 0H. no. No.1 nH.I no.1 No. doom nON «cmo.N 0N. Hm. AeN.no + «coco Ann.v A noH.t Aoo.No Ame. «e AHN.V r 00H. AoN.o r HHH.I Aoo.Hv + oom.l i ASN.V r nNH.I Aoo.o r ooo. uCOHuHuuooo cmHm oHanm NHe 0:8 .H 0Hao9 00m Aaoo :iH o>HunH5hoa Aooo SOHuuaanaH Auto coHuoHvoa Anacozo woucHa use rune: Aooo canon nozo capo: onv Hons» szo unucua "mmhoz a 9.x OHAoHua> Heuoo> Aom.v «0.1 omN.I Aoc.Nv HH. HON. Gt Aon.Nv HH. MHn. i¢ 3.3 no.1 ooo.i as: no.1 oNH.I 5.3 cc. nHN. Cd Ann.nv on.l Noooo.l O. 5.2 on. NHn. G‘ as: no. NOH.H noon uCOHuHuuuoo OHnflflm Dnn 0:h on«. you noHuaouuaooaa unoaHHH>uau a yupHmcou :OHsa «mm new ouHsoou coHnnouwox .n mqmNv cooHuadaoo HaaHOuaH :me Ammo HoooH one: Auoo encore one: am OHnoHua> nauoo> 89 nr In In 90 in Appendix C. The evidence reported in Table 3 lends support to this respecification. Each of the regressions explain approximately one-fourth of the variation in Si 82 is a t' significant, positive predictor of strike duration when one controls for the possibility that larger units, because of their enhanced bargaining power, have shorter strikes. This is seen by the negative and significant coefficients on SZ2 in both regressions. The coefficients on SZ and 3Z2 are both significant at the .01 level. Their beta weights also are comparable in magnitude. Previous studies which demonstrated the absence of a significant relation- ship between Size and strike duration may have failed to identify a relationship because of the assumption that the relationship was linear.12 The magnitude of the beta coefficient seen on WB (labor cost) in Table l is reduced considerably in the Stable 3 regression (from .46 to .21). Some of the variation eaxplained by WB variable in Table l is apparently now being czaptured by the size variables (82 and 822). WB, however, remains Significant . Turning to the final variable in the Bit vector, significant, positive coefficients can be seen on combined units variable (CM) in Table 2 and in the Table 3 regression. As expected, it appears to take longer to 13 settle strikes initiated by more heterogeneous units. There are more issues to be settled. Compromises made at 91 the bargaining table may also take longer to sell to the union membership. In addition, note that controlling for SZ and 8Z2, the strength of the positive relationship between combined units (CM) and strike duration does not diminish. It has a beta in both equations of .09. The Pit Variables As expected, US, union support for the work stOppage, has a positive Sign in the six regressions reported in Tables 1 through 3. The consistency of this performance is strengthened by a significant coefficient at the .05 level or better in five of the six regressions reported. The absence of international or national union support for a work stoppage does apparently mitigate determination among a local union membership to obtain the desired settlement. The employer may also perceive the absence of union support for the strike as sufficient justification for "holding fast." Little or no movement by an employer during negotiations, dissipating interest among the local union membership, and the ineligibility to :receive strike benefits may all be factors which contribute to Shorter strikes, other considerations held constant. The wage issue variable (EC) also exhibited a positive performance, as expected. This variable is more Significant, however, in regressions which omit Cit Variables. EC represents the fact that workers are striking primarily 92 over wage issues. The reason that economic considerations became an issue may be caused by the difficulty in identifying the revenues needed to fund the concessions which were demanded. A more salient, stable predictor of duration may be the financial condition of the employer taking the strike. The combined effect between EC and two of the variables in the Cit vector (Slack and tax burden) was insignificant.l4 The performance of SB, the supplementary fringe benefits variable, was also consistent across model specifications, but its sign was unexpected. AS a variable which represents a Specific type of economic concern, SB was expected to be positive. These results suggest that a union membership may be willing to strike longer when the issue relates to the magnitude of the weekly (or monthly) paycheck than when it relates to other, supplemental. benefits. Employers may also be more willing to compromise when diSputeS concern fringe benefits. This is because cost savings accrue when group benefit programs for health, dental or life insurance are established. As a general rule, the larger the employee group serviced with a group fringe benefit, the greater is the economies of scale. The strength of the relationship is relatively weak, however, and the number of observations (see Appendix B) makes interpretation for this variable also subject to considerable qualification. The last variable in the Pi vector, FN, the t 93 "first negotiation" variable, also exhibited a consistent performance across the six equations reported in Tables 1 through 3. Its negative signs, however, were insignificant. Further, a positive sign had been predicted. This suggests that during the recognition campaign, many of the more difficult issues may have been resolved. As a general rule, both employer and union appear to be no more (or less) willing than better established units to execute a first agreement and proceed with administering the new contract. Given the insignificance of FN, there is no reason to think that strikes occurring during first negotiation rounds will necessarily be Shorter. This evidence, however, does question the general prOposition that strikes which occur during the negotiation of first agreements Should be longer relative to the duration of strikes occurring during subsequent negotiation rounds. The Kit Variables Among the five variables included in this vector, only one, North (NO), was significant and its Sign not expected. Holding strikes in southern states constant, the evidence reported here suggests that strikes in northern states are Shorter than strikes occurring in other regions of the country. Contrary to expectations, this is consistent with the prOposition that bargaining units with a longer (and therefore more mature bargaining history) may be able rim 94 to resolve their differences more expeditiously. This qualifies the conclusion based on the results seen on FN that the length of the bargaining relationship is not a relevant factor. WR, the variable which represents the occurrence of a strike during the winter quarter, was positive in the six equations presented, but it never attained significance. In preliminary analyses of the data, season appeared to be a more relevant predictor of the type of employee most likely to initiate a strike. For instance, a positive correlation was found between street and highway strikes (STR) and the winter (WR) (r=.l7) as well as between education strikes and fall (r=.38). Organized workers would be expected to prefer strikes during the season that they think would cause the most inconvenient disruption in service delivery. A more exhaustive examination of this possibility is outside the SCOpe of this study. It is significant to suggest here that no significant or predictable relationship was found between WR and duration. The sign on SO (South) was also consistent. It was negative in the Six regressions reported, but never attained significance. This is consistent with a priori expectations, but its contribution to the explanatory power of the model is miniscule. Not a large number of strikes actually occurred in south during 1977-1978, so little weight can be given to this result. Consistent with the insignificant performance of rf tc Ce 95 WR, the interaction term NO*WR (strikes occurring during winter in the north), is negative twice and positive four times in the regressions reported. This variable is also never Significant. Apparently there are other, more salient factors which affect the duration of public employee strikes than season. Finally, the signs of rural (RU) were negative, as predicted, but never became Significant. AS one would expect, strikes in rural areas were slightly shorter than strikes in more pOpulated areas, but there is no evidence that this effect is significant. Organized workers in rural areas who have Opted for strike action may simply be more militant than has been acknowledged in previous studies. While this variable is a weak predictor of duration, RU could be a more salient determinant of strike frequency. It is also interesting that the magnitudes of the beta weights on RU drop slightly when it is entered in regressions having a curvilinear Specification for the size (822). In the Table 3 regressions, it has a Slightly lower significance level than in Table l or Table 2. Controlling for size, it is not surprising that RU becomes less significant. One justification for the prediction of its negative Sign was the fact that rural communities tend to be smaller and more highly interconnected. This is being captured, to a degree, by 82 and 8Z2. 96 The C. Variables It The Insignificance of the Number of Units Variable Perhaps the most unexpected result among the four variables associated with the Ci vector was the negative t Sign on NU, the number of bargaining units. Recall that a positive sign had been predicted. This expectation was based on the assumption that the employer should be the primary actor affected by the number of units that are recognized to bargain collectively. A greater number of units may, on the other hand, be also a reflection of the enhanced bargaining power of organized labor in the jurisdiction taking the strike. NU has a strong negative correlation with RE (r=-.25), the ratio of comparable employee earnings with the earnings of the striking bargaining unit. Earnings levels in jurisdic- tions with a relatively large number of bargaining units appear to be higher relative to the earnings of their comparable counterparts. With a greater comparative earnings advantage, there may be less incentive for labor to conduct long strikes which may ultimately yield only modest concessions. The fact that NU also represents the degree of bargaining leverage held by labor has apparently moderated the positive Sign expected on NU. This analysis has thus far considered strikes initiated in all types of jurisdictions. Many jurisdictions, 97 however, have few bargaining units. This is especially true of school districts and Special districts. A second possible explanation for the insignifi- cance of NU may be that no relationship was found because of a failure to control for differences in the type of governments taking a strike. The effect that the number of units has on the duration of strikes in school districts may be quite different from the effect found in counties and cities. Accordingly, separate regressions were run which considered the duration of strikes occurring in I I I 15 C1t1es, town and count1es. In this analysis, the mean value of NU is increased. This analysis is important for comparative purposes. As discussed in Chapter 2, much of the previous work on the duration of public employee strikes has selected non-education employees as the primary unit of analysis. A consideration of the performance of the variables used in this study can then be compared with the results obtained in previous studies. The Duration of Strikes in Towns, Counties and Cities The results of this analysis are reported in Table 4. In the left column regression, all variables which were found in previous analyses to be insignificant were omitted. In the right column regression, all predictors which were subsequently found to be insignificant were We Ca Wh. re] Co; dis Var 98 omitted. "Employee type" variables, however, were also included in the second regression. These results Show no appreciable change in the significance of the number of units (NU). Its sign became positive, but its beta weight was .00. This evidence, combined with the results for NU seen in Tables 1 and 3, suggests that the number of bargaining units may not have a direct effect on the duration of public employee strikes. There probably are, however, important indirect effects. Although NU contributes little to the explanatory power of the model, these regressions report higher coefficients of multiple determination than were seen in Tables 1, 2 or 3. The first regression reports an R2 of .32, while the second has an R2 of .31. In comparison to the explanatory power of the Burton-Krider regression results (r2=.10), a study which also considered non-education strikes, the explanatory power of the variables in this regression, and the relative consistency of their performance, were better.16 The coefficients of multiple determination reported in Table 4 were, however, comparable to a study which recently repli- cated the Burton-Krider model by analyzing 1974-1975 strikes. When using days idle as the dependent variable, this replication study reported an R2 of .28.1'7 The most consistent finding across all three studies was the discovery of a negative and insignificant sign on the size variable (SZ). SZ2 was also insignificant. In comparison AoN.o A Aomso no. AoH. . oxHuu- ouauHoa Amn.Nc A Azuav nN. cacao.H oxHuua noHuauuoa-cauu Hoo.o A «xenon Heamo oo. ooH. sasono so. noose. Hoo.Ho + Hoozo nH. new. «Juno. Houaano: AAn.Ho + Amoco 0H. «An. oxuuua noruo Hoo.Ho + Az on o .i .r AN eeooA Hm canon H H Hey we moo ouHa «on ANN.HV N HoHo HH.: can.i SOHuueoneH AoH.HV A Anny NH.i OON.r nevus; «cu Aoo.Ho + Auto oH. ANN. :OHuaHvoa «a AoA.No ANH.NV A AHmo H oN acmMA N HN ceNAH N soaHa Ano.Ho + Aozo Ano.o + Apzv nH.r HAn.r :uuoa no co. coo. nude: .u AAo.oo AAn.nV A Anny Ao<.o + Aomv no. nNo. An. oNo. uooo nonuH N co. Hoo. oaouH own: as ea «.0 Aqo.Nv AAm.No + one Amos Aoo.o AnN.Hv + Away 0 o O 0 g o O I I AH eecNA NN aeHno on an SOH «mm no noA HH was H unease one: «mu anon mnoHOHuuooo soon ueoHOHuuoou smHm oHoaHua> nouoo> noon uSOHuHuuooo noon ucoHuHuuooo mem oHnaHuo> neuoo> oouuoaxm peacock» uoHunsoo van n:30u .ooHuHu cH wcHuuaouo noxHuua up SOHuouzv or» up coHuquoun 05H .q manther, comparable employees. Similarly, there is no .zreason, based on these results, for employers paying Ik>etter than average wages to be Optimistic that the duration (Duf a strike, if one occurs, will necessarily be shorter. (Either factors apparently are more important once the strike has begun . The performance of these variables is also affected by the fact that only the most militant employee groups have been selected for examination. This reduced the variation in the expectation variables (Bit) relative t1<>> the variation for the same variables when considering 108 all bargaining units having recognition. As a direct result of this selection bias, fewer causal relationships are apparent from an examination of the correlation matrix found in Appendix C. Moreover, these expectation measures are probably better predictors of strike frequency than of duration. It is interesting that a similar conclusion was reached in a replication of the Burton-Krider strike model18 for the years 1974-1975. In this studylg, an alternative specification for an expectation measure, the ratio of change in private sector earnings to the change in public sector earnings, was found to be a more signifi- cant predictor of strike frequency and strike breadth than of strike duration. Some Concluding Considerations The summary results seen in the Table 6 regressions suggest there is still much to be learned about the determinants of strike duration. Note that among the nine variables considered in the second regression, two (WB and SL) had signs which a priori were indeterminant. One variable (822) was not included in the develOpment of the theoretical model. Two of the variables found to be significant (ME and NS) had signs which were predicted to lie in the Opposite direction. 109 The vector, K. was introduced so that factors zt' not captured by the other vectors could be controlled. None Of these variables were found to be significant enough to be included in the Table 5, 6 or 7 regressions. Some expected findings, but many unexpected results, were generated. This is not a negative signal, since it may be just as important in this stage Of the early develOpment of public employee strike theory to identify irrelevant factors as it is to identify significant ones. After many Of the less important predictors Of strike duration were omitted in Tables 5, 6 and 7, it is interesting that the explanatory power Of these regressions was not that different from the coefficients Of determination found in Table 1. On the positive side, the significance Of all of the regressions was high, as seen by the F scores. Many Of the predictors behaved consistently, regardless Of the model Specification. The explanatory power Of the regressions ranged from one—fourth to one-third Of the variation in the dependent variable. From a public policy point Of view, the factors B identified by the variables in the Ci and Pi t’ it' t vectors can not be affected by public policy once a strike has begun. The variables in the Li vector, however, do t represent Options that are available to employers in the event a strike occurs. The purpose Of Chapter 5 is to examine further the implications Of the results reported 110 in Tables 1 through 4 on these public policy variables. 111 Footnotes (Chapter 4) Recognition strikes, strikes occurring during the term of the agreement, and wildcat strikes accounted for only about 15% Of all reported strike occurrences in the public sector. These strikes are excluded from the analysis since they are much more likely to be symbolic protests to the public rather than a result of an interest in Obtaining better concessions. See, for instance, Ronald W. Glass, "Work StOppages and Teachers: History and Prospect," Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, NO. 8 (August, 1967), pp. 43446. 2 Census Officials have reported considerable difficulty in identifying whether bargaining units at the state level Of government are organized across occupational lines, or cut across departmental structures. 3 Eighteen Of the 558 strikes were not continuous events. In some instances workers struck for a day or more, decided to return to their jobs, and then soon thereafter initiated subsequent strike actions. This was defined as a single strike event. All days Of idleness for the same bargaining unit were summed together to reflect the total work days lost. Strikes occurring during the final two and one-half months Of 1978 were deleted because matched jurisdiction identification Census numbers and BLS case numbers were not available. Respondents are asked to indicate when the stOppage began and when the employees "returned to work." In calculating the number of work days idled, it is impossible to determine how many days falling within the strike period were holidays, or simply "non-work" days. In determining the number Of work days idled, the BLS thus assumes that local jurisdictions Observe the same holidays as federal government employees. These are New Year's Day (January lst), Washington's Birthday (3rd Monday in February), Memorial Day (4th Monday of May), July 4th, Labor Day (lst Monday of September), Columbus Day (2nd Monday of October), Veteran's Day (November 11th), Thanksgiving (4th Thursday Of November) and December 25th. This sample of jurisdictions includes all cities which have a pOpulation Of over 25,000, and all counties with a pOpulation over 50,000. Cities and counties with smaller pOpulations were selected on a random basis stratified by geographical area. 112 6 Robert C. Rodgers, "A Replication of the Burton-Krider Model Of Public Employee Strike Activity," Industrial Relations Research Association Series (1981), pp. 241-251. 7 For a discussion Of these studies, see Chapter 3. 8 David Britt and Omer Galle, "Industrial Conflict and Unionization," American Sociological Review, Vol. 37 (February, 1972), pp. 53-55. 9 Robert N. Stern, "Toward an Empirical Merger: Sociological and Economic Conceptions Of Strike Activity," 28th Annual IRRA Meeting (1975), PP. 58-61. 10 John F. Burton and Charles E. Krider, "The Incidence Of Strikes in Public Employment," in Daniel S. Hamermesh, Labor in the Public and Nonprofit Sectors (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975). 11 Robert C. Rodgers, Op. cit. 12 Depending on the strike deflator when states were used as the primary unit of analysis, a day's idle dependent strike measure could also have been adjusted disprOportionately when the day's idle variable was divided by the size deflator selected. 13 Although it is impossible to identify from the information obtained on the work stOppage questionnaire whether units were combinations Of occupational groups, the BLS codes onto machine readable data files information pertaining to the occupational categories Of the strikers. This is drawn from a review Of the press reports on the strike by the BLS coding clerks. 14 The interaction terms EC*SL and EC*WB were positive, as would be expected, but their coefficients were not significant at the 99% level Of significance. Their beta weights were .03 and .08 respectively. 113 15 An alternative analytic technique was also considered. Dummy variables were constructed tO represent each Of the four major jurisdiction types. With school districts as the comparison group, the results were consistent with the regression reported in Table 4. Consistent also with the findings on "employee type" variables was an inverse relationship between the duration of strikes in school districts relative to the duration Of strikes in other governmental units. John Burton and Charles Krider, Op. cit. Robert C. Rodgers, Op. Cit. John Burton and Charles Krider, Op. cit. Robert C. Rodgers, Op. cit. Chapter 5 Analysis Of Public Policy Variables Two Of the variables in the public policy vector, L had signs which were consistent with the theoretical it’ model. These were the injunction (IJ) and permissive law (PL). The third variable, mediation (ME), was significant but its positive sign was not expected. This chapter further analyzes these results by considering first the performance Of the IJ and PL variables. DO Court Injunctions Enhance or Deter the Duration of Strikes? The injunction variable IJ (representing the issuance Of an injunction sometime during the course of the strike) had negative coefficients in the Chapter 4 regressions, but it never attained significance. Injunctions sought by employers, presumably, do force strikers back to their jobs earlier than otherwise might have been the case. Initial discussion for this variable suggested that there are reasons for believing that injunctions might both reduce and enhance strike duration. This is why the sign on IJ was predicted to be indeterminant. NO information is available on the duration (if any) of the strike before the injunction was issued. An heuristic assumption for purposes of this analysis was that 114 115 employers usually seek injunctive relief shortly after a strike begins. It is important to note, however, that this assumption may or may not be valid. Employers who face unusually long strikes may choose to pursue a court remedy only after all possibilities for a settlement have been explored. Conceivably, this could take two or more weeks. This delay would moderate the magnitude and significance Of the sign on IJ. Unfortunately, data limitations preclude the possibility of disentangling these effects. With this caveat in mind, however, it is worthwhile to explore three additional questions. The effect of the court injunction may vary depending on the presence Of compulsory penalty laws, the size of the striking unit, or the type Of employee involved. These additional considerations are discussed below. DO State Compulsory Penalty Laws Make a Difference? Some states have compulsory penalties for employees who strike illegally. The employer, however, must first request from a judge a cease and desist injunction. Then the court has an Obligation under the law to fine the strikers or, depending on the law, their respective bargaining agent. The existence of a state compulsory penalty law, PE (coded equal to 1 for states having a mandatory penalty law and 0 for states without this 116 provision in their collective bargaining statute), may thus be a significant predictor Of strike duration. This possibility was examined in a regression analysis which included PE as well as all Of the significant predictors of strike duration identified in Chapter 4. With an expectation that the sign on the compulsory penalty law variable (PE) should be negative and its coefficient significant, the regression results confirmed a negative sign. Its significance was, however, inconsequential. The coefficient for PE was -.132, its t-score was .59, and its beta was -.03. Injunctions were considerably less common in states with compulsory penalty provisions in their public employee collective bargaining law than in states which did not have this provision. As shown in Table 7, among states with mandatory penalty laws, ten (10) injunctions were issued during 1977-1978. This constitutes 17% of the total number Of strike occurrences in these states. This is actually slightly lower than the prOportion of injunctions to the total number Of strikes in states which had no compulsory penalty law. This proportion was 20% (95 injunctions issued out Of 476 strikes initiated in these states). The compulsory penalties may have little relationship to strike duration because in practice, employers are no more (or less) likely to seek injunctive relief in states having these laws once a strike has mo (“Ne-{Hm m cosmmH OOOHuocsnOH mo Honesz one am am mm He m cm mmxauum mo Honesz mHHhmOOOm commuo OHSO mwmumh 3oz OHHSmQamm Bmz HusommHz camaroaz mchz hxosuamm mmmsmM maoaHHHH uOOHuOOOOOU «HanomaHmu mmumum msmH huHmOOm zuOmHOOBOU unoaqu mmumum .OHHm sump mwmaaoum xuoz mHm mumuuomom 3mH noan .Omaom mOHummHo muumaaoo “AmmmH ..u.o .couwaHnmmSV mmHuHHom mOOHumHOm noan uOuowm OHHnsm mo mumaEOm .OOHumuuchfiac4 OOOH>uOm unmammmsmz noan .uOAMH mo unmauumnmn .m.D .B. Isl N n m wH o H o 0H 0 H N mH H N cmnmmH IMMMNMMWI mOOHuOssnaH mo umnasz mo ambasz "moousom wumn mH0 00.3 mm. mow- as 00.3 00.. no _ 00.3 030 Ufiflfldhfl.) o .4 IV to v u: m: h m a- O. H N to v In «3 h» m «m o r! r: —4 we —c —4 r0 —c an —1 cu r» cu cu cw cw (V «V cu «V In HNMQMOF‘DO‘ 158 n:- 1-“-“ (“r-m"---“1“-