43"
a .. 43 fl ‘
i ,p, t.fi;{}
-r A." V E m h ?~ A 'ct-M
i- _ ,_\l‘_.'J,':.:.:,3 ‘0; €33 " J “i”
H ‘ r ‘3" ‘
., ‘3 13’ an? ‘77 a
. a
V ‘2
This is to certify that the
thesis entitled
FORECASTING THE MONEY STOCK
presented by
Philip Pfaff
has been accepted towards fulfillment
of the requirements for
Ph.D.
degree in Economlcs
\
Major professor
Date I 1-6-73
0-7 639
. ,‘ g 343‘; ..~.- g- .h- - armfi-
ABSTRACT
FORCASTING THE MONEY STOCK
by
Philip Pfaff
A number of economic models exist which have the money
stock as the endogenous variable. However, these models
have not been systematically exposed to what many maintain
is the ultimate test of an economic model: predictive per-
formance. The subject of this dissertation is the examin-
ation of the predictive performance of a cross-section of
money stock models.
The models examined ranged from mechanistic models to
two equation models estimated with TSLS estimation techni-
ques. Some models examined had explanatory variables which
primarily reflected the behavior of the banking system,
e.g. reserves and the discount rate, while other models had
explanatory variables which primarily reflected the private
non-bank sector, e.g. interest rates and income. The mech-
anistic models were either autoregressive models of the
money stock or money multiplier models which assumed that
the multiplier either did not change or changed at a con-
stant rate over the-forecast period.
Philip Pfaff
Predictive performance of the models for the 1961—1970
period was examined. Where parameter estimation was
necessary, 1947-1960 data was used. In order to reduce the
role of judgment in using the models, all models forecast
ex post, i.e. the actual values of the exogenous variables
were used. The root mean square error (RMSE) statistic was
used as the measure of predictive performance. Other pre-
diction evaluation statistics were used, but their ranking
of predicitve performance differed little from the RMSE
ranking.
The autoregressive seasonally adjusted money stock and
the no-change money multiplier model were the two models
which forecast with the lowest RMSE. The strong time trend
of the money stock data was one explanation of the good
predictive performance of the autoregressive model while
the relative stability over time of the multiplier con-
tributed to the low RMSE of the multiplier model.
The best performing economic models, i.e. models with
expanatory variables in addition to the lagged values of
the dependent variable, were a number of single equation
models. One had a short-term interest rate, income (or
permanent income), and the lagged dependent variable as
explanatory variables with all quantity variables expressed
in nominal or real terms. Another had total reserves plus
reserves released through changes in the reserve require-
ment, the short-term interest rate, and the discount rate
as explanatory variables. No two-equation model performed
Philip Pfaff
better than these single equation models just mentioned.
Predictive performance was improved in this dissertation
a number of ways. Including the lagged dependent variable
in a forecasting equation almost without exception improved
prediction performance. Linear combinations of the resi-
duals of prior period(s) when added to the constant term
of the equation also lowered the RMSE. Correction for
first-order autocorrelation also improved predictive per-
formance.
Where possible, the models were tested for the existence
of structural shift. In this study it was observed that
structural stability was neither a necessary or a sufficient
condition for a low RMSE forecast, i.e. in some cases where
the hypothesis that structural shift had occurred could not
be rejected, the model forecast with a low RMSE; and in
other cases where the hypothesis was rejected the model
forecast with a relatively high RMSE.
The impressive performance of the mechanistic models vis-
a-vis economic models in forecasting the money stock should
serve as a challenge to the econometric model builder. It
also indicates that such mechanistic models provide a tough
standard of comparison for conventional economic models.
FORECASTING THE MONEY STOCK
BY
Philip Pfaff
A DISSERTATION
Submitted to
Michigan State University
in partial fulfillment of the requirements
for the degree of
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
Department of Economics
1973
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The following people must be thanked for their help with
this dissertation. Foremost is Professor Robert Rasche for
being the ideal dissertation director. He was always
available with cogent advice and criticism. What merit
this dissertation has is due in large measure to his active
interest in the project.
The other two members of my dissertation committee,
Professor Maurice Weinrobe and Professor Carl Gambs, must
also be thanked for their assistance and guidance. The
standard proviso clause for a dissertation--i.e. all short-
comings of the dissertation are mine--is particularly true
for this one.
My wife Kristen must be thanked for her patience and
support during the dissertation ordeal. Finally my MSU
colleagues--both in and outside the Department of Economics
--must be thanked for helping make the dissertation exper-
ience a humane one.
ii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
LIST OF TABLES
Chapter
I. INTRODUCTION
II. FORECASTING WITH AN ECONOMETRIC MODEL
Forecasting models
Non-econometric forecasting models
Econometric forecasting models
Judgment and forecasting with an
econometric model
Forecasting errors in econometric models
Sources of forecasting error
Reducing forecasting error
Evaluation of the performance of a
forecasting model
Conventional test statistics
Other test statistics
Studies of forecasting performance
Comparison with mechanistic models
Other prediction evaluation statistics
Summary
Appendix to Chapter II
III. ECONOMETRIC MODELS OF THE MONEY STOCK
Money multiplier models
Money supply models
Money demand models
Simultaneous equation models
Money supply and demand models
The Teigen model
Large econometric models
Summary
iii
Page
ii
vi
14
22
27
28
32
32
36
42
47
Chapter Page
IV. PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF NAIVE MONEY STOCK
MODELS 48
The models 48
Mechanistic models of the money stock
The money multiplier models
The decomposed money multiplier models
Summary
Evaluating prediction performance 54
Results 55
Autoregressive models
Evaluating predictive performance
The Burger multiplier model
Summary 70
Appendix to Chapter IV 72
V. FORECASTING WITH SINGLE EQUATION MODELS
OF THE MONEY STOCK 73
The models 73
The conventional money demand function
The per capita money demand function
The real money demand function
Evaluation of the money demand models
Money supply: the Brunner model
Money supply: the Teigen and Gibson models
Evaluation of predictive performance 101
General evaluation
Constant adjustments
The Chow test .
Predictive performance 107
Structural stability of single
equation models
The conventional prediction evaluation
statistics of the money demand models
The Brunner model
The Teigen and Gibson models
Adjustments of the constant term
Summary 120
iv
Chapter
VI. TWO-EQUATION MODELS
Introduction
The models
The money multiplier model
The Brunner—Meltzer model
The Teigen-Gibson models
The estimated models
Evaluation of prediction performance
The results
Forecasting the money stock with
recursive models
Forecasting the money stock with
non-recursive models
Forecasting the interest rate
Summary
VII. CONCLUSION
Forecasting performance
Improvement of forecasting performance
Two-equation models ’
Evaluation of prediction
Income and interest elasticities
Summary
BIBLIOGRAPHY
NOTATION APPENDIX
DATA APPENDIX
Page
121
121
123
134
136
145
146
146
147
149
150
151
152
153
161
164
Table
2.1
4.1
4.2
LIST OF TABLES
Ranking of prediction test statistics
Estimated coefficients of seasonal
dummies for Equation 4.10
Standard error's of autoregressive
models as the number of lagged
terms vary
COOper test statistics for auto-
regressive money stock models
COOper test statistics for money
multiplier models
Predictive performance of mechanistic
money stock models
Annual predictive performance of
mechanistic money stock models
Ranking of the predictive performance
of mechanistic models
Annual predictive performance of
selected models
Summary of notation for Chapter V
Estimated coefficients of the money
demand model
Estimated coefficients of the per
capita money demand model
Estimated coefficients of the real
money demand model
Selected estimated money demand models
Estimated coefficients of annual money
demand models without lagged variables
vi
Page
26
60
60
63
63
64
66
68
68
74
76
78
80
82
Table
5.7
5.20
5.21
Interest and income elasticity of
quarterly money demand models
Annual money demand models with
lagged variables
Interest and income elasticity of
annual money demand models
Quarterly nominal money demand model
fitted over three time periods
Estimated coefficients of the
Brunner model
Brunner's regressions
Estimated coefficients of the
Teigen model
Comparison of the Teigen model
Estimated coefficients of the
Gibson model
Comparison of the Gibson model
Selected F-ratios for (n + m) = 100
Chow test statistics
Predictive performance of money
demand models
Annual predictive performance of
quarterly money demand models
Predictive performance of the
Brunner model
Annual predictive performance of
quarterly money supply models
Predictive performance of the
Teigen model
Predictive performance of the
Gibson model
vii
Page
87
88
90
91
93
94
96
98
100
102
.106
108
110
112
114
115
116
116
6.'7
Predictive performance of selected models
with constant adjustment terms
Estimated coefficients Of the C-series
models
Estimated coefficients of the money
supply
models
equations of the D-series
Estimated coefficients of the money
demand
models
Predictive
models
Predictive
models
Comparison
equations of the E-series
performance of two-equation
of the money stock
performance of two-equation
of the interest rate
of the prediction of the
money stock and the interest rate
Annual predictive performance of
selected models
viii
Page
118
128
132
133
138
138
139
144
CHAPTER I
INTRODUCTION
Many economists view the predictive performance of an
economic model as its ultimate test. In light of this, in
recent years increased attention has been paid to the pre-
dictive performance of econometric models. Most of this in-
terest, however, has been focused on forecasts of GNP, or
its principle components, while little attention has been
paid to models that can be used to forecast the money stock.
This dissertation is an attempt to begin filling in this
lucuna. This project will inevitably go beyond the question
of which money stock model forecasts best. For example, it
will have implications for the question of the importance
of the role of money in the economy. The dissertation will
lalso briefly discuss a variety of prediction evaluation
statistics, and examine how well they perform in actual
practice. But the basic question will remain: how satisfied
can the econometric model builder be with the current
models of the money stock.
frhe dissertation will be organized in the following
fashion. Econometric forecasting and its evaluation will be
surveyed in Chapter II. An introduction to the various
technixgues of evaluating the performance of predictions will
also be part of this chapter. Various money stock models
which can be used for forecasting are then described in
Chapter III. The next three chapters discuss the appli-
cation of these models to forecasts of the money stock for
the 1961-1970 period. Data from the 1947-1960 period are
used to estimate the parameters of the models. Chapter IV
will deal with meChanistic money stock models, Chapter V
with single-equation models and Chapter VI with simple
simultaneous equation models. Chapter VII will tie to-
gether the results derived from these chapters.
CHAPTER II
FORECASTING WITH AN ECONOMETRIC MODEL
Until recently economic forecasting has been an
"artistic, subjective, and personal" endeavor [Klein,
1968, p 9], but with the develOpment of theory--both
economic and econometric--and the availability of
reasonably reliable and extensive data and machines
capable of manipulating this data, economic forecasting
has become more objective. Most forecasting models
used by economists still require the use of the fore—
caster's judgment in order to make forecasts with
small errors. Nevertheless the results of mOst
forecasting models can be replicated and the fore-
cast analyzed. It may, in fact, be possible to as-
certain, at least partially, the source of a forecast
error. The develOpment of a number of different models
each explaining the same economic variable (e.g. GNP)
has allowed us to compare the forecasting ability of
particular models (as Opposed to comparing economic
forecasters who would usually have difficulty con-
sistently replicating their forecasts).
In this chapter econometric forecasting and its eval-
uation will be discussed. In Chapter III econometric
forecasting of the money stock will be discussed.
3
A. FORECASTING MODELS
l. Non-econometric forecasting models
The business cycle attracted the early economic fore-
casters. For example, Wesley Mitchell and the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) attempted to forecast
the behavior of economic aggregates such as GNP and the
national income components by tracking leading indicators:
economic events which usually preceeded turning points in
the business cycle.l'
Since World War II, forecasts based
on data from surveys of the buying intentions of consumers
have been made. These forecasts using anticipations data
have been used to predict either consumption (usually of
durables) or investment. While on the whole such fore-
casts are unreliable [Evans, 1969, p 494], they are fre-
quently more reliable than mechanistic forecasts,3 and so
. . . . 4
this forecasting technique continues to be used.
1. Use of the leading indicator methodology was not limited
to the NBER. For an example a bit removed from the NBER
mainstream, see Roos, 1955, pp 369-379.
2. For a review of early attempts at economic forecasting,
see Zarnowitz, 1968, 1968; R003, 1955. For a recent dis-
cussion of leading indicators and NBER methodology, see
Evans, 1969, pp 445-460.
3. Mechanistic forecasts depend solely on the statistical
characteristics of the data series, e.g. an autoregressive
model. A good example of such a mechanistic model is Jus-
ter's, an autoregressive model with up to 8 lagged values
of the dependent variable. Juster, 1969, pp 226-229.
4. This grossly oversimplifies the case for forecasting
with anticipations data. It is, however, an example of a
widely used forecasting technique which forecasts
{(‘t. [{(l.(.((l([‘ [l.[( [I [2" (.[11 [.‘ I ill! [.[Z'lll 4" (III 6". l ( (I [I
Economists (usually along with businessmen and govern-
ment officials) have been frequently surveyed to determine
what they feel certain economic aggregates will be in the
future. Since the forecast aggregate depends upon the
judgment of the participants in the survey, this forecast
is frequently called a judgmental forecast. Zarnowitz
[1967] examined the prediction performance of these fore-
casts and found that judgmental forecasts performed better
than did no-change and same-change extrapolations of the
series being forecast. Other studies have confirmed that
judgmental forecasts predict better than mechanistic fore-
casts.5 Of course the success of recent judgmental fore-
casts must be viewed with caution since the judgments of
many individual economists (and others) may have been
influenced by forecasts made with econometric models.
2. Econometric forecasting models
The econometric model has greatly increased the ob-
jectivity Of the econometric forecast.6 While there were
variables of interest to the economist, but which makes
little use of econometric techniques or the more conven-
tional economic data series.
5. For example, see Stekler, 1970, pp 74-91. Smyth, 1966
summarizes the performance of Australian judgmental fore-
casts and compares them with judgmental forecasts for
other countries.
6. Forecasting it seems will never be completely objective.
Much judgment is required to successfully specify, estimate,
and use even (or especially?) the largest econometric fore-
casting models.
earlier macro-econometric models, the Klein-Goldburger
model is the water-shed in the use of macro models by the
economist.7 Christ's review article of the Klein-Gold-
burger model [Christ, 1956] included one of the first eval-
uations of the predictive performance of an econometric
model. The shift in attitude towards econometric models
which occurred around this time can be seen in two articles
which discussed econometric methods of forecasting. Bassie,
for example, saw too many inflexibilities introduced by
the econometric approach to forecasting, and maintained
that such an approach would remain impractical. [Bassie,
1955, p 33]. R003 [1955], on the other hand, gave an
optimistic prediction of the future role of econometric
models in forecasting.
Econometric models have come a long way since the Klein-
Goldburger model. Many are quite small, consisting of one
or two equations; while others are quite large.9 Some have
10
been designed explicitly for forecasting, while others
have been designed to examine the behavior of a certain
7. The review article by Fox, 1956 brings this out most
strongly.
8. R005 stated that "the modern econometric forecaster,
viewing the economy as an elastic membrane in disequilibrium,
is forever on the altert to identify new impressed forces
that might reinforece or negate his forecasts." Roos, p 395.
9. For example, The Brookings model. Duesenberry, 1965.
10. For example, the Wharton-EFU model. Evans, 1968.
sector of the economy.11 There are, in fact, a number of
models which can be used to forecast the money stock some
of which will be discussed in the next chapter.
3. Judgment and forecasting with an econometric model
While the objective nature of forecasts generated by an
econometric model will be emphasized in this study, judg-
ment is necessary for successful econometric forecasting.
For example, in the actual forecasting situation the values
of the exogenous variables must be chosen. In many cases
the constant terms of the equations are adjusted to re-
flect the forecaster's estimation of the size and impact
of structural shifts in the economy, or the behavior of the
residual term of the pervious periods. Further adjustments
may be made if, after making a preliminary forecast, the
resultant prediction of the endogenous variables simply do
not look correct to the forecaster.12
Since we want to compare the predictive ability of vari-
ous econometric models, and not the various forecasters,
the role of judgment in using a forecasting model must be
minimized. Thus in evaluating forecasts actual values of
exogenous variables for the periods forecast (henceforth,
ex post values) will be used rather than the values of the
11. The FRB-MIT model, for example, emphasized the role of
the financial sector of the economy.
12. For a description of this process, see Evans, 1972,
pp 1126-1128, and Klein, 1968, pp 50-51.
exogenous variables which are themselves predicted when
making forecasts (henceforth, ex ante values), and while
constant adjustment terms may be used to improve the per-
formance of the models, the adjustments will be mechanical.
This approach rules out evaluation of forecasts using ex
ante data and equation adjustments based on the forecaster's
feel of the economy.13 Forecasts using ex ante data fre-
quently predict better than forecasts using ex post data
even though both forecasts make use of constant adjust-
ments.14
B. FORECASTING ERRORS IN ECONOMETRIC MODELS
1. Sources of forecasting error
The world is stocastic, not deterministic, and therefore
we will always be confronted with forecasting error. The
relationship between the dependent variable (Yt) and the
independent variable (xt) can be expressed in the form
(assuming that the relationship between the two is linear):
(2.1) Yt = Bo + let + et
where et is a random disturbance term. Standard
13. Klein, 1968, p 42 maintains that such judgmental adjust-
ments are an important element in any realistic forecasting
situation. So a loss of realism is the price of using the
ex post approach.
14. See Haitovsky, 1970 and Su, 1971. Possible explanation
of why the use of ex ante data leads to better forecasts
than the use of ex post data is discussed in these articles.
econometric theory is that the total variance of the fore-
casting error of the prediction15
(2.2) Yt = B0 + 31x0
. . . 16
is given by the expreSSlon
m 2
2 2 1 (x0 ' X)
(2.3) SF = s 1 + ;'+ n 2
t=l (Xt ‘ X)
,This suggests that there is a lower limit to forecasting
accuracy.l7 Estimating the forecasting error for more
complex situations is difficult. Klein [1968, pp 27-28]
has developed a numerical technique for determining the
standard error of forecast for equations with lagged
endogenous variables, while Feldstein [1971] has con-
structed an estimator for the interval of the forecast
error when the exogenous variables themselves are stochas-
18
tic. But except for the most elementary models,
A
15. §t is the predicted value of Yt given K0. Bo and B1
are estimated values of B0 and BI' (Yt - Yt) is the fore-
cast error, and sF is an estimate of that error.
16. Kmenta, 1971, pp 240-241. 52 is an estimate of the
variance of (Yt - (B0 + BIX)). For the multiple regression
case, see Kmenta, 1971, p 375.
17. This expression tells us explicitly that the further
away the independent variable is from its mean, the larger
the standard error of forecast.
18. But three rather restrictive assumptions underlie Feld—
stein's estimation of the interval: the stochastic distur-
bance is not autocorrelated, lagged endogenous variables
are not used, and only linear models are considered.
10
estimation of the forecast interval is difficult. Even
when the forecasting error can be estimated, however, the
error is usually greater than the accuracy requirement of
the forecaster [Klein, 1968, p 40], and therefore the fore-
caster is forced to resort to an activity called "fine
tuning." [Evans, 1972, p 952]. This, of course, implies
the application of judgment to forecasting with econometric
models.
The forecaster frequently must use preliminary data
which is to be subsequently revised. There is a trade-off
between data accuracy and reporting speed [Stekler, 1970,
pp 102-121], although in recent years the quality of pre-
liminary data has improved. [Zellner, 1958; Cole, 1969].
19
While this is a problem for the forecaster, the evaluator
of forecasting performance usually has the revised data
available.20
An econometric model assumes that during the period of
the fit, the relationship between the variables in the
model remain fixed (or at least changes are allowed for by
dummy variables). If the model is used for forecasting,
the relationship is assumed to remain fixed. But the world
l9. Klein, 1968, pp 68, 42. Klein sees it as an important
research task.
20. Poor data may influence the construction and use of a
econometric model. Do adjustments to the constant term
compensate for poor data, or for structural shifts? This
question is not dealt with here.
11
is not that neat. Changes do occur.21
Such change may be
compensated for by adjustment of the constant term al-
though frequently Change is either not noticed, or is
difficult to quantify. COOper maintains that statisti-
cally significant shifts do occur even within a short time
horizon.22 Usually the constant term is adjusted in the
short run and the model is periodically reestimated. Klein
[1968, p 51], however, has pointed out that a freshly esti-
mated system needs adjustment as much after a year or two
as it does after four or five years. This adjustments,
unfortunately, are usually based on the forecaster's feel
for the economy and for how expected changes will appear
in the model. Since we are interested in examining the
behavior of the forecasting model and not the forecaster,
as mentioned above, adjustments of this type will not be
considered.
A forecasting model may be misspecified, and if the
misspecification biases the disturbance variance term,
forecasting error is unnecessarily high. The three mis-
specifications which do increase forecasting error are
omitted variables, incorrect functional forms, and
21. Another possibility is that the model was misspecified.
In this case, while the world may have remained fixed, the
hypothesis that this was the case could be rejected by a
test for structural stability.
22. Cooper, 1972, pp 900-915. Cooper fitted his models
over the period 1949-1 to 1960-4, and found that there was
a significant shift of many of the equations in the models
during the 1961-1 to 1965-4 period.
l2
heteroskedasticity of the disturbance terms. Careful
examination for misspecification is usually not part of
the model estimation procedure.
Another source of forecast error is incorrect estimation
of the values Of the exogenous variables. Evans [1972,
pp 954-956] maintains that the only correct way of evalu-
ating the forecasting ability of a model is by examining
its ex ante forecasting ability. But as Cooper [1972,
p 816] has pointed out, only by comparing the accuracy of
ex post forecasts is the judgmental element held con-
23
stant. In this study, therefore, the ex post values Of
the exogenous variables will be used.
2. Reducing forecasting error
When a forecasting model has autocorrelated residuals,
adjustment Of the constant term is explicitly specified by
the model. The adjustment for first order autocorrelation
for a T period forecast is
T
(2.4) A = p e
t+T t
where A is the constant term correction factor, p is the
autocorrelation coefficient, t is the period when the
forecast was made, T the length of the forecast, and e
is the observed residual for that period.24 A refinement
23. Stekler [Evans, 1972, p 1141] in his discussion of the
Evans approach makes the same ObServation.
24. Goldberger, 1962. See also Klein, 1968, pp 68, 51-55.
13
of this adjustment i525
(2 5) A: =IpT et + pet-l
' t+T 2
The over-adjustment that results from exceptionally large
residuals in the latest Observed quarter is thereby reduced
[Evans, 1972, p 966], and, where this adjustment has been
used, the forecasting performance of the model has been
improved. Predictive performance of models not corrected
for autocorrelation is frequently improved by introducing
adjustments based on the residuals of prior periods. One
such correction factor was used by Haitovsky [1970,
2
pp 504-505]: 6
u e + e
(2.6) A = t'1 t'2
t 2
The desired properties of estimated models, e.g. minimum
variance of the forecast endogenous variable, depend upon
error specification of the estimated model meeting the
.assumptions of the classical linear regression model.
Otherwise the model is said to be misspecified. The
restrictive nature of these assumptions is usually acknow-
ledged in the course of estimating the model, but whether
the residuals actually meet these assumptions is rarely
25. This adjustment is frequently called the Goldberger-
Green adjustment. Evans, 1972, p 966; Haitovsky, 19728,
pp 319-320.
26. Such a correction term, of course, implies that the
model is autocorrelated, and assumes that the best cor-
rection technique is a second-order correction scheme
with p1 = .5 and p2 = .5.
14
asked. Four tests for specification error have been
develOped by Ramsey [1971] and used by Gilbert [1969] to
determine the prOper specification for the demand for
money function.
C. EVALUATION OF THE PERFORMANCE OF A FORECASTING MODEL
When a number Of econometric models have the same
dependent variable, comparison of the different models is
inevitable. There are a number of approaches to making
such comparisons.27 For example, a model can be evaluated
on its use of a priori knowledge, or its use of appropri-
ate estimation techniques,28 but the ultimate performance
criterion is frequently seen to be the model's forecasting
ability.29
It is this aspect of the performance of
econometric models of the money stock which is the focal
point of this Study.
Goodness-Of-fit statistics have sometimes served as a
proxy for direct examination of forecasting performance.
The forecaster usually wants maximum mileage from his data,
and so is reluctant to reduce his sample size. This is
27. See Naylor, 1966, pp 311-315; and 1971, pp 154, 158 for
a discussion of the four methodological positions regarding
this question. See also Zecher, 1971.
28. McCarthy in Cooper, 1972, p 934.
29. Naylor, 1966, p 318 maintains that prediction is the
ultimate test of a model.
15
30 But since a model
particularly true with large models.
may perform quite differently outside its estimation period,
goodness-of-fit statistics do not necessarily indicate good
forecasting ability. Nelson [1972], for example, has shown
that within the estimation period the consumption-invest-
ment block of the Penn-FRB-MIT model explains a high pro-
portion of the variation of the block's endogenous variables,
while outside the estimation period a significantly higher
prOportion of that variation is explained by a mechanistic
model. Such results are not uncommon. The goodness-of-fit
criteria may also promote "data mining," i.e. estimating a
wide range of possible models and using the model with the
best fit statistics. In such a case goodness-of-fit cri-
teria provides little indication of the validity of the
model.31
It is generally agreed, therefore, that the more rigor-
ous test of a model is to forecast with the model, and
evaluate its predictive performance. [Jorgenson, 1970,
p 214]. Using either ex ante [Evans, 1972] or ex post
[COOper, 1972] values for the exogenous variables, the
endogenous variables are predicted and then compared to
actual values. Occasionally prediction evaluation stOps
30. Of course once a model has been estimated and used for
forecasting, after a while it is possible to study its pre-
dictive performance. This has been done in Evans [1972] for
the Wharton-EFU model and the OBE model.
31. Jorgenson, 1970, p 214 elaborates on this problem.
16
32 but usually summary statistics are calculated to
there
aid in the evaluation of the prediction performance of a
particular model. These statistics are the subject of this
section.
1. Conventional test statistics
The two principal prediction evaluation statistics are
the root mean square error (RMSE) statistic
1 n A 2
(2.7) RMSE _ ///n Zt=1 ( t t)
and the mean absolute error (MAE) statistic
(2.8) MAE = l
n
The MAE statistic is preferred by Klein because of its
simplicity and ease of understanding [Klein, 1968, p 40],
while others prefer the RMSE because it has a quadratic
, 33 . . . .
loss function. Two variations of these two statistics
are the mean squared error statistic (which, however, does
not have the same dimension as the error term), and the
mean percent absolute error statistic. Occasionally the
32. For example, Christ, 1956, where the predictive per-
formance of the Klein-Goldburger model is tabulated.
33. The loss function Of the MAE statistic in linear. Pro-
ponents of the RMSE statistic assume, at least implicitly,
that they become more concerned about an error as it in-
creases in magnitude. For more on this, see Fromm, 1964.
17
rnage of the prediction error is used [Fromm, 1964, p14].
Naylor [1971, pp 159-160] suggests the possible use of
Spectral analysis and various non-parametric tests.
2. Other test statistics
34 but rarely used,
Another approach, frequently prOposed
is to regress the forecast values on the actual values of
the prediction model, and to examine the test statistics
. . . 2
assoc1ated With the regreSSion. In other words, the R of
the regression
. A=A+A +
(2 9) Yt Bo BlYt et
would be examined along with the standard error of the
regression and the closeness of B0 to zero, B1 to one.
This approach will be used in Chapter IV.
The model can also be examined to determine whether
structural shift has occurred between the estimation period
and the forecast period.35 This is the most powerful of
the univariant tests with the same level of Type I error
(the incorrect rejection of the null hypothesis).36 The
34. See Klein, 1968, p 39; Mincer, 1969, pp 9-10; and
Naylor, 1971, pp 159-160.
35. An implicit assumption of any test for structural
stability is that the model is correctly specified. Re-
jection of the hypothesis that no structural shift has
occured may indicate that the model is in fact misspeci-
fied. Ramsey, 1969, has developed tests of misspecifica-
tion.
36. Jorgenson, 1970, p 218. The test is from Chow, 1960.
18
structural shift statistic as described by Chow37 has an F
distribution. COOper described a less powerful alternative
structural shift statistic, i.e., that of the adjusted ratio
of the sum of squared residuals over the forecast period
to the reduced form mean squared error over the fitted
period, which has a Chi-square distribution.
While stability may be desirable in a forecasting model,
a Clear-cut relationship does not necessarily exist between
tests for stability and the forecasting ability of a
model. [COOper, 1972, p 919]. The techniques described
ignore the interdependence in simultaneous equation models.
Also coefficients may change over time in such a way that
forecasting performance of the model improves. 'And, of
course, the test for structural change may fail (i.e. a
Type I error is made).38
Another approach to the evaluation of predictive per-
formance is to ask whether the model forecasts better than
a naive or mechanistic model. The simplest naive models
are the no-change model
2.1 i? =Y
( 0) t t-l
and the same change model
(2.11) Yt = 2 yt_1 - yt_2.
37. This test is described by Kmenta, 1971, p 370.
38. See p 26 where we evaluate the actual performance of the
test.
19
There are, Of course, other forms for naive models.
In recent years a growing use has been made of the auto-
regressive model39
A = p
(2.12) yt {i=1 Bth_i
. . 40
as a standard of comparison for econometric models. A
more SOphisticated mechanistic model is the Box-Jenkins
model. If the process being specified is stationary, i.e.
the process repeatedly returns to the neighborhood of the
mean, then the process can be discribed by a combination of
an autoregressive equation (such as just described) and a
moving average equation:41
(2.13) § = A + p B Y
0 2i=1
- " q ' o o
t 1 t-i + ut 2j=1 AJut-
J
The criteria for proper identification (i.e. what are the
optimum values of p and q) are minimization of the number
Of parameters and minimization of the mean squared resi-
duals. When the process is not stationary (e.g. GNP,
prices), successive differences are taken until the model
exhibits stationarity. First differences are usually suf-
ficient to bring about a stationary situation with economic
data [Nelson, 1973, chapter IV, section 1]. A model whose
39. For a description of such models, see Klein, 1968, p 43;
or COOper, 1972, pp 830-831.
40. p is uSually-chosen so that standard error of the model
is minimized.
41. ut-j = Yt-j - Yt-j’ A0 is the mean of Y.
20
values of p and q are both 1, and where stationarity
results from taking the first difference would be
(2.14) Y = BlAYt—l + A0 + u ,- Alu
t t
t-l'
Identification and estimation of the model requires itera-
tive techniques for which computer programs exist. [Nel-
son, 1973].42
Another statistic used to evaluate the predictive per-
formance of a model is the Theil inequality coefficient
[Theil, 1966, pp 27-28]--the ratio Of the MSE statistic
c>f the model to the MSE of the no-change naive model43
n A
Zt=1(Yt' Yt)2
n 2
t=l Yt °
(2.15) 02 =
2
frlie value of U will be a positive number. The model
‘thich predicts perfectly has U2 = 0; if the forecast per-
formed only as well as the ‘no-change model, then U2 = l.
44
.A variation of this statistic is the Janus coefficient
n+m
(2.16) J2 = (l/m) Zt=n+1(?t - Yt)2
(1/n) 23:1(Pt - Yt)2
¥
433.» Box, 1970 presents this model in all its rigor. Nelson,
19 72A, pp 11-14 has a brief summary of the above while
Nelson, 1973 gives a rather complete explanation of the
technique.
‘413- In some write-ups of the coefficient, Yt and Yt are
first differences. See Theil, 1961 and Theil, 1966.
44. Gadd, 1964.
21
This coefficient resembles the F ratio, but since time
series data usually exhibit autocorrelation and the fore-
cast values in the numerator are obtained by extrapolation
from those in the denominator, it does not have a F
distribution.
The numerator of the Theil and the Janus Coefficients
are sometimes decomposed and these decompositions are said
to measure the degree of bias, unequal variation, and in-
complete variation in the forecasting model. [Thei1,
1966]. But Jorgenson [1970] has questioned the usefulness
of the decomposition. This issue will be discussed in
the Appendix of this chapter.
An evaluation technique for single period ex ante fore-
casts made with simultaneous equation models has been out-
lined by Haitovsky [1970]. Haitovskey examined the error
Of the individual equations when ex ante and ex post data
are used, as well as the effect of three forms of con-
Staint adjustment. The effects that different data sets
and different constant adjustments have on the entire
System is also examined. This technique revealed that con-
tiant adjustments did improve the 1966-3 Wharton-EFU fore-
caSt [Haitovsky, 1970], and the 1968-3 OBE forecast per-
formed better with ex ante values of the exogenous than
with ex post values. [Su, 1971]-
\
45 . The three forms of constant adjustment were no adjust-
ment, average residual adjustment (A = [ut-l + ut_2] / 2),
and the adjustment actually used by the forecaster.
22
D. STUDIES OF FORECASTING PERFORMANCE
Studies of the forecasting ability of money stock models,
unfortunately, are rare. With the exception of work done by
the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis,46 the predictive performance of monetary models is
at best a side issue. Tobin and Swan [Tobin, 1969], for
example, maintained that the forecasting superiority of a
naive model and a trend model over two examples of a Fried-
man-Swartz money model lessened the significance of the re-
lationship between the money stock and Friedman's permanent
income. Christ's [1971] comparison of models of the finan-
ci a1 sector described the predictive performance of the
models, but concentrated on the model's structure and theo-
retical foundation rather than its actual performance.
This section describes the measurement of forecasting
Performance of econometric models other than money stock
mOdels as a means of illustrating forecasting evaluation
tect‘lniques.
1- Comparison with mechanistic models
Frequently the prediction performance of an econometric
model is compared to that of a naive model.47 Christ [1956] ,
46 - This research will be discussed in the following
chapters.
47- There are test statistics which make implicit use of
Such criteria. The R2 statistic, for example, compares the
explanatory power of the regression against the average
Value of the dependent variable.
23
for example, compared a no-change naive model with the
Klein-Goldburger model and found that the naive model fre-
quently forecast certain components Of GNP better than the
econometric model. Evans [1972, p 967] in his large-scale
study used both a no-Change and a same-change model as
standards of comparison. A variety of naive models has
been used. Smyth [1966] compared three specifications of
the same-change naive model to forecast the Components of
Australia's GNP‘19 along with an average (for the entire
period) change model. In this case, only the average
change model50 occasionally outperformed the econometric
model. Some studies of judgmental forecasts have also used
naive models as a standard of comparison. [Zarnowitz,
19 67, pp 83-88] .
The autoregressive model has come into favor as a stan-
dard of comparison for forecasting models. For example,
Green [1972, p 51] compared autoregressive models with 2
and 4 lagged dependent variables to various equations of
#1
48- His same-change model for forecasts up to 6 months was
Yt+T = Yt + T (Yt - Yt-l)
Where T is the length of the forecast.
49 - These were
3 .
(1/3) 21:1 %AYt_i, and
(1/5) {i=1 sAYt_i.
%AYt
%AY
t
50- This of course is an ex post concept.
51. Equation 2.12.
24
the OBE model in predicting components of GNP. The OBE
model proved to be superior to the autoregressive models.
Jorgenson [1970, pp 203, 208] found that a fourth order
autoregressive model for different investment components
predicted better than the poorer performing econometric
models in his study. But this was an arbitrary way to
choose the number Of lagged terms for the autoregressive
model of each investment component. Cooper [1972, pp 830-
831] chose the number of variables which would minimize
the RMSE of the equations and found that the autoregressive
model frequently outperformed (i.e. had smaller RMSE) the
equations of some large econometric models of the U. S.
economy .
53
The Box-Jenkins generalization of the mechanistic model
was used in Nelson's [1972A] study of the term structure of
interesst rates, and again [Nelson, 1972B] in his study of
the Penn-FRB-MIT model.54 In the latter case, within the
k
52 ~ COOper, 1972, p 917 summarized his results by Choosing
the best performing model for 33 endogenous variables. No
Slngle model was superior. Of the 33 variables, the econo-
metric model performed best for both the period of fit and
of forecast 6 times, the autoregressive model performed
best 13 times, and the autoregressive model performed best
1501‘ the period of fit 8 times, and for the forecast period
times.
53- Equations 2.12 and 2.13.
54 - Two examples from the Penn-FRB-MIT model study (Nelson,
l972B, p 915) are the equations for gross national product
GNPt = GNPt_l + .615(GNPt_1 - GNPt_2) + 2.76 + ut
and non-farm inventory investment
25
estimation period the econometric model itself contributed
much towards minimizing forecasting error; but outside the
estimation period the Box-Jenkins model tended to perform
55 It seems probable that this model will super-
better.
cede the other mechanistic models in those cases where
time or expense is not a constraint.
2. Other prediction evaluation statistics
The Theil inequality statistic has been widely used for
prediction evaluation. For an example, see much of the work
of Stekler [1970]. Use of the decomposition of the Theil
inequality statistic is also widespread. Theil has used
the decomposition on a range of projects [Theil, 1961, 1966]
as had Kuh [1963] in his study of capital investment, Smyth
[1966] in his examination of Australian judgmental fore-
casts, and Evans [1972] in his analysis of large scale
models of the U.S. economy. But nowhere in these investi-
gations was an attempt made to discuss the Jorgenson cri-
tique of the approach.
The test for structural shift has been used, but the
I = . I + 1.69 + + . + . .
t 581 t-l ut 0013 ut-l 742 ut_2
TPhe first equation illustrates the difference and auto-
Jregressive forms of the model, the second the autoregres-
SSive and moving average forms of the model.
555. Nelson also used a composit prediction using both
ItKbdels. The composit model was better than the Penn-FRB-
DTIT model for 12 out of 14 variables while it was better
tfllan the Box-Jenkins model for only 7 out of 14 cases.
Nelson, 19728, p 915.
26
test results at times conflict with other prediction evalu-
ation statistics. For example, the MSE for real total con-
sumer expenditures over the forecast period in COOper [1972,
p 875] study is lowest for the OBE model yet this model ex-
hibited the greatest degree of structural shift [p 902].
This pattern, however is not consistent. Current plant and
equipment expenditure, for example, in the Fromm model has
the lowest MSE [p 877] and least structural shift [p 903].
Such inconsistancy is also seen in Stekler's [1970, pp 65,
69] comparison of inventOry forecasts. Ranking forecasts by
the Theil inequality statistic differs from ranking by the
structural shift test statistic. For example, See Table 2.1
'where ten models are ranked by relative lack of structural
shift56 and the inequality statistic for two different time
periods. While structural stability is a desirable char-
acteristic for a forecasting model, it is obviously not
necessary for good forecasting performance.
TABLE 2.157
RANKING OF PREDICTION TEST STATISTICS
lLack of Shift 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
I31 1 9 6 3 5 2 4 7 8 10
I12 1 10 2 4 9 3 5 9 8 6
¥
556. Since the degrees of freedom associated with each of
the F ratios are different, it is the significance level
which is ranked.
557. From Stekler, 1970, p 65, Table 3-1, and p 69, Table 3-4.
Tfiie first row is the ranking of each model based on the Chow
twist for structural shift. The other two rows give the rank
(*5 the model cited in the first row based on the Theil
27
E. SUMMARY
This chapter has presented a range of statistics which
can be used to measure the predictive performance of
econometric models. These statistics will be used to eval-
uate the forecasts made by the money stock models which are
discussed in the next chapter.
‘
jJmequality statistic. U1 is for the period 1948-3 to 1964-
‘4; U2 is for the 1953-1 to 1964-4 period.
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER II
THE THEIL INEQUALITY COEFFICIENT
Theil attempted to evaluate the predictive performance of
an econometric model by means of what he called an inequal-
ity coefficient: the scaled1 mean squared error2
(2A.l) (l/n) 22:1 (Pi - Ai)2
The most useful characteristic of the coefficient, Theil
maintained, was the decomposed form of the coefficient
which measured three attributes of the forecasting model.
The usual form of the decomposition was
2 ._ 1— 2 2
(2A.2) (l/n){‘i‘___l(Pi - Ai) = (P -,A) + (SP - SA)
+ (1 - r2) SP SA
where
s: = (l/n) [2:1 (Pi - P)2.
s: = (1/n) 2231 (A1 - 32, and
‘—
.1. Theil used at least two different scaling factors:
( 7'7I7HTEP§'+ /‘TI7HT§K§')2 (Theil, 1961, p 32), and
(l/n)ZA: (Theil, 1966, p 28).
2. Pi is the predicted value and Ai the actual value of the
IPredicted variable.
28
29
(1/n) 2 (Pi - P) (Ai - A)
r:
S S °
P A
The first term of the decomposition according to Theil
measured bias, the second measured unequal variance, and
the third measured unequal covariance.3 Theil maintained
that if the values of the first two decomposed terms appro-
ached zero, this spoke highly of the predictive performance
of the model.4 Theil's only defense of this argument was
graphical.5 In spite of this rather casual approach to-
wards validating this method Of prediction evaluation, the
inequality coefficient and its decomposition have been
widely used.6
Jorgenson, however, in a recent article questioned the
meaningfulness of the decomposed statistics by examining
the expected values of the first two decomposed terms.7
The expected values of the first decomposed term was found
to be8
3. Theil, 1961, p 34-35; Theil, 1966, pp 30-32. An alter-
native decomposition is given in Theil, 1966, p 33; but
this does not change the argument which follows.
4. This, of course, implied that the third term would in
such a case approach the value of the scaling factor.
5. Theil, 1961, p 36; Theil, 1966, p 31.
6. For example, see Stekler, 1970; and Cooper, 1972.
7. Jorgenson, 1970.
8. inz = 2(xi - K)2 where Xi is the value of the explana-
tory variable at the time of prediction and K'is the
30
' __ _ 1 X- - X
(2A03) B
.o mamv.o Hz
SDCOE NH zucoE m Samoa m Space N SDCOE H HOUOZ
pesos e
Ashamedhom Eases NH 0» a mo mmzmc
mdmooz spasm smzoz OHBMHzamomE so mozazmoamma m>HeoHomma
m .v mamas“
65
be known over the forecasting period. The fact that the
autoregressive model performed as well as it did over the
full twelve months shows the forecasting power of such a
model. Since seasonal adjustment of the money stock series
is done after-the-fact, even the SA autoregressive money
stock model is partially ex post. The only model using no
information from the forecast period itself is the auto-
regressive NSA money stock model, and even this model per-
formed well. Its RMSE for the one month forecast was three
times that of the M1 mOdel, but less than twice the M1
model for the 12 month forecast.
As the estimated models predict further away from the
1947-1960 estimation period, it would be expected that pre-
diction performance would decline. The annual RMSE sta-
tistics of 12 month forecasts, displayed in Table 4.6, show
that such is the case. The autoregressive multiplier model,
however, for forecasts of 3 or more months had a uniform
RMSE over the entire 1961 to 1969 period. The performance
of the money multiplier models whose forecasts depended
28 deteriorated in the late
only upon immediately prior data
1960's. While this was not unexpected in light of the
results of the COOper test, it also suggested that the money
crunches and the impact of Regulation Q increased the vari-
ance of the time trend of the money stock in the late 1960's.
28. Use of the no-change and the same-change multiplier
models does not require the estimation of coefficients which
are based on data from prior periods.
66
womv.m
Nvmm.a
hth.N
ammo.H
«Nvo.m
momm.m
momm.~
Nth.N
von.m
ommo.H
o2
Nomv.oa
oaom.h
mmva.h
Hmoa.m
mmhm.h
momm.m
movo.m
moma.va
Nmma.v
mbHH.m
m2
oomm.o
Nth.NH
mmva.m
ommo.oH
onwn.oa
mmmh.m
oaam.h
mamm.h
mhva.m
mwmm.h
0v:
mmwo.m
ooam.m
mamv.m
Hde.m
mamo.m
mmom.o
mmom.H
mmmv.a
«Hmb.m
vmmm.H
mvz
loH.o
oNoH.m
mhoa.h
mmoH.m
mhmm.h
omom.o
mmbo.m
mmmm.o
mHm~.v
omom.v
.m
mmom.m
mamm.m
momh.m
mmam.m
mmmm.N
mmmm.~
oovo.m
NS
Noao.H
ommn.o
Hhhv.a
ommm.H
mmmH.H
Hmmm.o
mvmv.o
Hmwm.o
Hohh.o
mmmm.o
H2
mqmooz MUOBm wmzoz UHBmHZ¢mUMS m0 m02¢2m0mmmm m>HBUHQmmm AdDZZd
m.v mqmdfi
moma
Iaoma
mood
mood
hood
coma
mood
vwma
mood
mood
Hood
Ham»
67
This could account for the poor prediction performance of
most of our models during this period.
The ranking of the RMSE, the MAE, and the MPAE Of the
different models are the same for one month forecasts and
change little for 12 month forecasts. (The rankings of the
monthly models are shown in Table 4.7). The rankings re-
mained the same for quarterly models over the entire fore-
cast period. The differences were due to the fact that the
mean error measures have a linear loss function while the
RMSE statistic has a quadratic loss function and so is more
strongly influenced by outliers.
The regression of predicted values on actual values gave
little statistically meaningful information. The intercept
term of the regression did at times differ from zero, but
the difference was rarely statistically significant. The
slope in most cases remained close to one, and R2 close to
.99. Only the standard error of estimate seemed to indicate
anything, and that was not much different than what the more
conventional measures suggested. Therefore, this prediction
evaluation method will not be used in subsequent chapters.
The ranking of the standard error of these regressions for
the various models is shown in Table 4.7.
3. The Burger multiplier model
In recent years economists at the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis have studied:the possible use of multiplier
7 Rank
01¢le-
OKDGJNICD
Year
Burger
M1
M2
M3A
M6
68
TABLE 4.7
RANKING OF THE PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE
OF MECHANISTIC MODELS
(Rankings based on 12 month forecasts)
RMSE Value
M3A 2.5513
M6 3.9897
M3C 4.2155
M1 4.3810
M3B 4.4373
M2 7.4997
M4B 14.6002
M4A 23.1651
.M5 25.6654
M4C 35.8358
MPAE Value
M3A 1.1131
M3B 1.6453
M1 1.9361
M6 1.9412
M3C 2.06.8
M2 3.5001
M4B 4.8557
M5 10.2336
M4A 10.4939
M4C 15.2384
TABLE 4.8
A
Y
SE of
on Y
M3A
M6
M2
M1
M3C
M3B
M4B
M4A
M5
M4C
Value
2.2335
2.2594
2.8916
2.9884
4.2013
4.4440
14.7280
23.2814
25.9279
36.0477
ANNUAL PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF SELECTED MODELS
(RMSE of 1 month forecasts)
1964 1965
0.6890 0.6602
0.2842 0.3263
1.3784 1.2369
1.5968 2.0097
1.6116 2.0221
1966
1.4993
0.5798
1.5459
2.2468
2.0221
1967
1.6307
0.8581
1.8937
1.5754
2.2851
1968
0.9333
0.5324
1.5273
2.1761
1.5784
1969
0.0456
0.3517
1.4578
2.5995
2.6253
69
models for forecasting.29 The most successful multiplier
forecasting model was constructed by Burger [1972] who
/
3
used the following monthly model:
_ 3
(4.16) m _ 80 +151 [(1/3) Zi=lmt-i] + 82 TB
The coefficients of the regression used to forecast each
month's multiplier were estimated by OLS using the previous
36 months' observations. Each forecast, therefore, depended
only on the data of the preceeding 3 year period.31 The
multiplier was then used to forecast the SA money stock ex-
actly as shown in Equation 4.8.
The use of the Treasury bill rate removes this model
from the mechanistic model catagory. However, of the vari-
ous models considered, it would seem most appropriate to
compare the Burger model to the multiplier models. Table
4.8 lists the annual RMSE statistics for this model along
with the RMSE statistics for the no-change multiplier model
and the three monthly autoregressive models.
In comparing the models we find that the RMSE of the
autoregressive SA money stock model is consistently quite
29. A review of this work can be found in the Burger, 1972
article.
30. TB is the lagged percentage change in the Treasury bill
rate, the Di's are seasonal dummies.
31. In this study, the forecasting equation was eStimated
once. Burger's approach would have required the eStimation
of 108 foreCasting equations if forecasts were made for the
1961-1970 period.
70
smaller than the RMSE of the Burger model. The Burger
model, however, except for 1967, outperformed the other
models considered in this Chapter. Considering the com-
plexity of the Burger model (especially when compared to
the autoregressive money stock model), and its inability
to outperform a mechanistic model, it is difficult to be-
come particularly enthusiastic about its forecasting
abilities.32
D. SUMMARY
The results of this chapter can be summarized briefly.
(l). The autoregressive SA money stock model forecast best
for time periods up to 6 months. For 12 month forecasts
the no-change multiplier model forecast with smaller error.
For all models, the RMSE usually increased as the period of
the forecast lengthened. (2). The performance of the auto-
regressive NSA money stock model, the only model which did
not to some degree use ex post information, forecast poorer
than the two models mentioned above, but its relative fore-
casting ability did improve as the length of the forecast
increased. (3). The minimum standard error of estimate is
an appropriate statistic for selecting the proper number of
lagged terms for the autoregressive forecasting model.
32. In his article, Burger showed that the use of the RPD
base gives inferior predictions in comparison to the use
of the monetary base. Our data above (compare Model M33
and M3C to MBA) confirms Burger's conclusion.
71
(4). The difference which exists between the various pre-
diction evaluation statistics (RMSE, MAE, and MPAE) can be
accounted for by the loss function implicit in each sta-
tistic. The test statistics of the regression of predicted
on actual values tended to statistically insignificant.
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER IV
THE RATIO MULTIPLIER MODELS
33
A. THE RATIOS
a = (DTM - TDM) / DDP
DDO / DDP
9)
ll
" TD/ TDM
DJ
ll
0
ll
(CURN - CURR - CURB) / CURR
k = CURR / DDP
r = RSU / (DTM - TDM + TD)
r' = RSRPD / (DDO + TD)
t = TDM / DDP
B. DEFINITIONS
M = CURR + DDP
B
l RSU + (CURN - CURR - CURB) + CURR
r (a*DDP + t*DDP) + (1 + C) k*DDP
B
2
RSRPD = r' (a'*DDP + a"*t*DDP)
C. THE DECOMPOSED MULTIPLIER
m = M/B (1 + k) / [r(a + t) + (1 + C)k]
1
m = M/B (1 + k) / [r'(a' + a"t)]
2
33. Notation is listed in the Notation Appendix.
72
l
8
l
CHAPTER V
FORECASTING WITH SINGLE EQUATION
MODELS OF THE MONEY STOCK
In this chapter a number of single equation models that
can be used to forecast the money stock will be evaluated.
In the first section the different models will be described
and the coefficients, estimated over the period 1947-3 to
1960-4, will be presented. The various prediction evalua-
tion statistics and the use of the constant adjustment
term will be discussed in the second section. The fore-
casting performance Of the various models over the 1961-
1970 decade will be the subject of the third section.
A. THE MODELS
The coefficients of a number of version of six different
money stock models will be estimated. Three of these six
models can be described as money supply models; the other
three will be called money demand models.1 The money demand
function will be first specified in conventional form: the
nominal money stock regressed on nominal values of income
or wealth and either a short or a long term interest rate.
1. See pp 36-37 where the meaning of money demand and money
supply models within the forecasting context is discussed.
73
74
The other two money demand functions will have the quantity
variables scaled by either population or the GNP price
deflator. These models are in log-log form. The money
supply models will include three versions of the Brunner
linear money supply model, the Teigen free reserves equa-
tion, and the equation Gibson prOposed as an alternative
to the Teigen equation.
The notation used in this chapter is summarized in Table
5.1. Each of the six models will be identified by a
letter. The variables included in each model will be
identified by the letters which follow the model identifier.
TABLE 5.1
SUMMARY OF NOTATION FOR CHAPTER V
Log-log nominal money demand model.
Log-log per capita money demand model.
Log-log real money demand model.
The Teigen money supply model.
The Brunner linear money supply models.
The Gibson model.
"113.10 000:»
Yield on commercial paper.
Yield on long-term Aaa bonds.
The Federal Reserve discount rate.
The difference between S and F.
Y Gross National Product.
W Permanent income (defined in footnote 2 below).
RRSL Total reserves plus reserves released through
changes in the reserve requirements.
><"11L"'U)
BA, BB, BC The three versions of the Brunner model.
D Dummy variables in the Teigen model.
S Seasonal dummy variables.
-L Model includes a lagged dependent variable.
-A Model corrected for first order autocorrelation.
75
The letters which follow a hyphen will indicate whether the
model had either a lagged dependent variable and/or has
been corrected for first order autocorrelation.
l. The conventional money demand function
The conventional single equation money demand function is
(5.1) 1n M = B + B
+
0 1n R + 82 1n Y e
1
where R is either the commercial paper rate or the long-
term bond rate, and Y is either GNP or permanent income.
The estimated coefficients for different versions of this
~model are given in Table 5.2.3 (The t-ratios are given
underneath the coefficients).
The signs of the estimated coefficients conformed to
conventional economic theory.4 The value of R2 was high
with the lowest value being .96. But at the same time the
values of the Durbin-Watson statistics were low, e.g. for
regressions not corrected for autocorrelation or with a
lagged dependent variable, they were between 0.17 and 0.21.
2. The following expression was used to compute the per-
manent income:
19 i
YP = 0.114 0.9 Y
t+l Zi=0 ( ) t-i
This expression was developed by deLeeuw, 1969.
3. Notation heading the columns are given in the Notation
Appendix.
4. The only exceptions were models ALW-A and Blw-A, where
the estimated coefficient for the interest rate variables
were positive. However these coefficients were not signi-
ficantly different than zero.
76
TABLE 5.2
ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS OF THE MONEY DEMAND MODEL
2
Model RMCP RMLB Y Y? Lag Const Rho R /SE D.W.
ASY —0.0345 .4271 2.3616 .9700 .2140
A -3 4041 23.9443 24.0774 .0153
zAsw -0.0049 .3591 2.7760 .9667 .1654
9 -0.5083 22.6158 32.4503 .0161
EALY -0.0344 .3982 2.5442 .9643 .1907
f -1.2302 18.6082 25.8986 .0167
l
I
.ALW -0.0293 .3710 2.7374 .9673 .1815
( -1.1105 19.5880 32.7377 .0160
lASY-L —0.0180 .0833 .8462 .2733 .9967 .6531
-5.2234 4.6825 20.4712 2.5536 .0050
iASW-L -0.0108 .0281 .9553 .0673 .9955 .5378
. -3.0381 1.4644 18.0959 .4400 .0059
TALY-L -0.0417 .0624 .9045 .1482 .9965 .7555
* -4.7865 3.7263 21.8499 1.3016 .0052
'ALW-L -0.0367 .0390 .9488 .0697 .9959 .6584
-3.9434 2.0815 18.9722 .4854 .0056
i
;Asy-A -0.0153 .2490 .00 .7701
i -2.4751 6.2567 .0059
(Asw-A -0.0095 .1742 .00 .5139
7 -1.3166 3.7022 .0069
ALY-A -0.0219 .2249 .00 .7750
-0.8305 5.0995 .0062
ALW-A 0.0235 .1356 .00 .5481
0.8759 2.9865 .0070
ASY-LA -0.0189 .1013 .8039 .3719 .65 .9982 1.7774
-4.8237 3.7748 12.2279 2.1111 .0037
Asw-LA -0.0179 .0663 .8812 .2045 .75 .9980 1.7468
-4.2946 2.5712 13.3468 1.0566 .0039
ALY-LA -0.0557 .0999 .8394 .2581 .65 .9980 1.8220
-4.0003 3.4974 12.1638 1.3514 .0039
ALW-LA -0.0459 .0523 .9368 .0573 .65 .9978 1.6683
-3.1931 2.0956 14.2495 .2929 .0042
77
When these regressions were corrected for first order
autocorrelation, it was found that a first difference
equation minimized the standard error for those regres-
sions without a lagged dependent variable.5 Some individual
coefficients of the various models were not statistically
significant, but there is little pattern to this Situation.
Only those money demand models which had GNP and the short-
term interest rates as explanatory variables had t-ratios
of above 2.0 for all the estimated coefficients. This was
the case whether or not the model had a lagged dependent
variable, and whether or not it was corrected for auto-
correlation.
2. The per capita money demand function
The quantity variables (as opposed to the interest rate
variables) Of the money demand function can be expressed in
per capita form. This transformation in some cases caused
a considerable difference in the values of the estimated
coefficients. The estimated parameters for the per capita
regressions (and t-ratios for the coefficients) are given
in Table 5.3.
The values of R2 for the models without a lagged variable
and not corrected for autocorrelation ranged from 0.51 to
5. A scanning technique was used to estimate the value of
p, i.e. various values of 0 were used to estimate the
parameters, and that value of p which gave the lowest stand-
ard error was choosen as the estimate for p. See
Hildreth, 1960.
78
TABLE 5.3
ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS OF THE PER CAPITA MONEY DEMAND MODEL
Model RMCP RMLB Y Y? Lag Const Rho Rz/SE D.W.
BSY -0.0276 .1790 5.3098 .5496 .1256
-2.2311 5.8328 23.2958 .0182
BSW -0.0225 .1581 5.4716 .5053 .1328
-1.7407 5.1392 24.0815 .0190
BLY -0.0882 .2024 5.2102 .5892 .1486
-3.2198 6.8483 25.9745 .0174
BLW -0.0763 .1804 5.3711 .5388 .1707
-2.6370 6.0177 26.6514 .0184
BSY-L -0.0172 .0445 .9270 .1574 .9573 .7638
-4.4814 3.9600 22.1001 .6466 .0056
BSW-L -0.0143 .0321 .9523 .0832 .9519 .6829
-3.5378 2.8676 21.7761 .3231 .0059
BLY-L -0.0443 .0521 .9022 .3027 .9605 .8671
' -5.0769 4.5511 21.9321 1.3035 .0054
BLW-L -0.0366 .0378 .9328 .2004 .9540 .7668
-3.9314 3.2712 21.4870 .8053 .0058
BSY-A -0.0121 .1341 1.00 .7901
-l.8759 2.8067 .0061
BSW-A -0.0071 .0723 6.1061 0.95 .9426 .6178
-l.0188 1.2283 13.2266 .0065
BLY-A -0.0194 .1122 1.00 .8304
-0.7232 2.1872 .0063
BLW-A 0.0074 .0437 6.3132 0.95 .9415 .7010
0.2967 .7757 14.4380 .0065
BSY-LA -0.0183 .0586 .8247 .7310 0.70 .9741 2.0811
-3.8337 3.1042 10.2235 1.5259 .0044
BSW-LA -0.0180 .0529 .8380 .6876 0.75 .9738 1.9778
-3.7200 2.8275 10.2018 1.3480 .0044
BLY-LA -0.0636 .0856 .8062 .7063 0.65 .9754 2.0359
-4.3107 4.0893 11.0888 1.6640 .0042
BLW-LA -0.0527 .0623 .8594 .5200 0.65 .9733 1.8090
-3.6763 3.3968 12.0509 1.1956 .0044
79
0.55. These values, relatively low for time series data,
are partly due to the value of the per capita money stock
essentially remaining unchanged over the estimation period.
The natural logarithm of the per capita money stock was 6.66,
at both the beginning and the end of the estimation period,
and ranged between 6.61 and 6.70.
The estimated coefficients of three of the four regres-
sions with neither a lagged variable nor corrected for auto-
correlation had t-ratios above 2.0.6 If the estimated con-
stand term was ignored, all the regressions with a lagged
_ dependent variable whether or not corrected for autocor-
relation had coefficients with t-ratios above 2.0. The
Durbin-Watson statistics behaved in the per capita money
demand function as they did for the nominal money demand
functions, i.e. the statistic was close to 2.0 only when the
regression was corrected for autocorrelation and included
a lagged dependent variable.
3. The real money demand function
A money demand function with the quantity variables
divided by the implicit GNP deflator was also estimated.
The estimated coefficients and their t-ratios are shown in
Table 5.4. The R2 values of the regressions ranged from
0.15 to 0.32 for regressions without a lagged dependent
6. The exception was model BSW.
7. The inclusion of the lagged dependent variable, of course
biases the Durbin-Watson statistic towards 2.0.
8C)
TABLE 5.4
ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS OF THE REAL MONEY DEMAND MODEL
Model RMCP
csy -o.0487
-3.3595
csw -0.0433
-2.9488
CLY
CLW
CSY-L -0.0216
-3.8014
csw-L -0.0235
-4.3652
CLY-L
CLW-L
CSY-A -0.0229
-2.4371
csw-A -0.0173
-l.8009
CLY-A
CLw-A
CSY-LA -0 0217
-2.9993
csw-LA -0.0234
-3.3452
CLY-LA
CLw-LA
RMLB
-0.1549
-5.3836
-0.1436
-4.8387
-0.0588
-4.4175
-0.0613
-4.9437
-0.0898
-2.3998
-0.0605
~1.8149
-0.0748
-3.6082
-0.0703
-3.9486
Y
0.0900
2.1226
0.1353
3.6969
0.0539
3.3383
0.0613
3.8869
0.2290
2.5418
0.2129
2.5698
0.0553
2.2135
0.0824
3.0400
YP
0.0683
1.6676
0.1128
3.1344
0.0582
3.9667
0.0633
4.4675
0.0937
1.3262
0.0754
1.2601
0.0615
2.6663
0.0751
3.4304
Lag
0.8495
17.5519
0.8633
18.6359
0.7979
15.8350
0.8127
17.1339
0.7428
9.4154
0.7691
9.8693
0.6835
8.8146
0.7353
10.4954
Const
4.4592
18.2401
4.5870
19.5556
4.3290
22.5537
4.4541
23.8945
0.4393
1.7790
0.3472
1.4316
0.7013
2.8938
0.6212
2.6441
3.5387
6.4242
4.3915
10.3446
3.7605
7.8712
4.5682
13.3659
0.9592
2.2988
0.7942
1.8700
1.1604
3.0694
0.9440
2.6514
Rho
0.95
0.90
0.85
0.60
0.60
0.55
0.55
2
R /SE
.1769
.0222
.1505
.0226
.3590
.0196
.3185
.0202
.8828
.0084
.8910
.0081
.8913
.0081
.8988
.0078
.8710
.0088
.8619
.0091
.8715
.0088
.8588
.0092
.9190
.0070
.9222
.0068
.9232
.0068
.9251
.0067
D.W.
.2194
.2085
.2740
.2770
.8960
.9223
.9966
1.0446
.8429_
.7331
.9263
.8106
1.7687
1.8191
1.7842
1.7877
81
variable, but when the lagged dependent variable was
included in the regression, the value of R2 approached
.90. The value of the dependent variable declined over
the estimation period and the range of the natural loga-
rithm of the real money stock was small, from 4.91 to
5.03. The latter fact especially may partially explain
the low value of the R2 term.
The coefficients of most models had t-ratios of above
2.0.8 The autocorrelation coefficient was less than 1.0
in all cases, and the pattern of the Durbin-Watson sta-
tistic was similar to that of our previous two cases.
4. Evaluation of money demand models
The estimated interest rate and economic activity co-
efficients of the money demand models discussed above are
low. The highest interest rate coefficient is 0.15; the
highest income coefficient is 0.43, and the highest per-
manent income coefficient is 0.36. Table 5.5 lists the
results of some other studies of the money demand function.
The estimated coefficients of other studies listed in this
table are higher than those obtained in this study with
similar variables. These studies, however, were all esti-
mated over time periods which were different than that used
in this study, and none of the other studies use the same
8. The exceptions were Model CSY-L, Model CLW-A, and all
Inodels which have both the short-term interest rate and
‘permanent income as eXplanatory variables.
82
..me a .amma .uumnafloi .ocoomm mzu ca Hmmu “muflmmo
mom pom Hmmu mum cofimmmummu uwuwm 0:» ca wmwuflucmsv Had .mump Hmsccm "pumnaflw
.Hmmm a .woma .umacflmq. .m» new
mom: ma mmflnmm meoocw Hmmu Umuoomxm muflmmo Mom m.cmEUmwum .mump Hmsccd "umapflmq
..HmHH m .ommH .3OLUH .uospoum Hmcoflum: um: we wEoocH can .mmflumm pcwuso
mcu ma Came» been one thmp magmafim>m ummummc Ho .cuom wash mo ma xooum
xmcoz .mmpmum pmuHCD mzu m0 moflumwumum Hmofluoumflm Eouw sumo .mump Hmscca «30:0
.Hmoma .umaammi
.pmms Hwaamm mmfluwm xooum MmCOE :0 ucmEEOU How uxwu mmm .mamp >HH0#HMSO "Hmaam:
Ac.ucooc m.m mamas
83
vom.
mmm.
mwo.
hmh.
mmo.
vvm.
womaoo.
mmoo.
mnamoo.
mmmm.
mum.
mmm.
mm\ m
N
mmm.o
NmHH.0I mvhh.o
ov.vl
ovmv.01
mvH.m
omo.m
mmam.o
Hmmm.01
mmm.m
MNH.N
umcoo
Ho.ma
mh.va
mmvh.o
Hmo.a
mmm.o
~ma.o
evo.o
mmao.ea
mmom.o
mmq mesa
mqmooz
vm.N
thH.o
mv.m
HmmH.o
mhmH.m
ommm.o
vmmm.mh
Hmmm.o
ooowNH omHN.o
oom.o
mvHN.mH
who.a
wad
m.m
mmo.o
mqmdfi
mm.vl
vaN.OI
om.ml
NomN.OI
mwm.¢a
mam.OI
vmmm.ml
moam.0I
mmmm.ml
movm.ot
OAZMCH mQZmCH
www.ml
th.oI
bmwv.ml
vOH.OI
mUSmGH
0242mm wmzoz omefiEHBmm QMBUMAmm
mmmHImHmH
ommalmvma
mmmalhmma
mmlhwma
ooflumm
mafia
gymnafiu
umaoflmq
3050
umHHmm
HmUOZ
84
series as was used here. Heller's regressions were closest
to the regressions whose estimates appear in Table 5.2, but
he apparently used an unusual money stock series to obtain
his estimates.9 Even so, his interest rate coefficients
were close to those in Table 5.2.
All the models other than Heller's model listed in
Table 5.5 were estimated with annual data. In order to
determine what impact this would have on the values of the
coefficients in Tables 5.2, 5.3, and 5.4, the money demand
equations were reestimated with annual data. Table 5.6
gives the coefficients and the t-ratios for the annual
money demand functions without a lagged dependent vari-
10
able. There is little difference between the annual and
quarterly models. The coefficients for both the interest
rate variable and the economic activity variable continue to
11
be low. The largest interest rate coefficient is -.15
12
while the highest economic activity coefficient was .43.
9. It is impossible to determine from Heller's description
of his data what money stock series he used. He cited as
the source of his data The International Monetary Fund,
Intennatéonaz Financiaz Statibticb. It would appear that
the data series he used from there was derived from Flow-
of-funds data. He never eXplained why he used this source
for his data. Interestingly, he did use the Federal Reserve
Bu££eth--the best source for money stock data--for his
interest rate data.
10. These regressions were estimated with average data for
the year. '
ll. This was for Model CLY. Model CLW had an interest rate
coefficient of -.14. The next highest coefficient was -.08.
12. This was for Model ASY. The two models cited in foot-
note 11 had estimated coefficients of .097 and .086 for the
MODEL
ASY
ASW
ALY
ALW
BSY
BSW
BLY
BLW
CSY
CSW
CLY
CLW
ESTIMATED
RMCP
-0.0452
-1.6360
-0.0406
-1.4070
-0.0367
-1.1320
-0.0325
-0.9958
-0.0684
-1.8225
-0.0622
-1.6434
The top values
Values are the
85
TABLE 5.6
COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL MONEY DEMAND MODELS
WITHOUT LAGGED VARIABLES
RMLB
-0.0152
-.02325
-0.0168
-0.2490
-0.0780
-1.2647
-0.0773
-1.2235
-0.1458
-2.0908
-0.1416
-1.9758
Y
.4345
9.3172
.3745
7.9122
.1879
2.4364
.1777
2.8243
.1195
1.1265
.0968
1.1435
YP
.4151
8.7557
.3647
7.6523
.1706
2.2880
.1696
2.7348
.0959
.9387
.0864
1.0392
Const
2.3282
9.1637
2.4500
9.5531
2.6627
12.5292
2.7317
12.9572
5.2502
9.2127
5.3843
9.8207
5.3901
12.7647
5.4563
13.2465
4.3005
7.0689
4.4390
7.6210
4.5514
10.3668
4.6111
10.8368
R2/SE
.9672
.0168
.9634
.0177
.9594
.0187
.9570
.0192
.4846
.0191
.4623
.0195
.4976
.0189
.4840
.0191
.1865
.0236
.1599
:0240
.2420
.0228
.2277
.0230
D.W.
1.2577
1.5552
1.0668
1.3391
1.1017
1.1863
.9885
1.1397
1.5809
1.5663
1.3719
1.4344
are the estimated coefficients, the bottom
t-ratios.
86
Log-log models with a lagged dependent variable yield
not only an impact elasticity but also the steady state
elasticity. Table 5.7 gives these elasticities for the
interest and activity variables for the quarterly money
demand functions. Only one model has a steady state elas-
ticity greater than 1.0; the nominal money demand regression
with the long-term rate and permanent income. But it takes
25 quarters before the elasticity reaches one-half its
steady state value.13 The adjustment time is also long for
the rest of the nominal money demand models and the per
capita money demand models. The real money demand models,
however, in all cases reach at least one-half of their steady
state elasticities by the fifth quarter. Correction for
autocorrelation of all three sets of models lowers the value
of the steady state elasticity and shortens the half-life
of the adjustment process.
The estimated interest rate and economic activity coef-
ficients of the annula money demand models with lagged
coefficients were approximately the same size as the quar-
terly models. The coefficients for the annual money stock
models with a lagged dependent variable are given in Table
5.8. As would be expected, the coefficients of the lagged
activity coefficient. The latter was the lowest of the
economic activity coefficients.
13. The first and second quarter elasticities are also given
in Table 5.7 as well as the half-life of the adjustment, i.e.
the length of time necessary to reach one-half of the steady
state elasticity.
87
TABLE 5.7
INTEREST AND INCOME ELASTICITY
OF QUARTERLY MONEY DEMAND MODELS
Model B l a s t i c i t y Half
Impact Quarter 1 Quarter 2 Steady State Life
ASY-L -.0180 -.0332 -.0461 -.1170 5
.0833 .1538 .2134 .5416
ASW-L -.0145 -.0279 -.0404 -.1989 10
.0452 .0873 .1262 .6214
ALY-L -.0417 -.0794 -.1135 -.4366 7
.0624 .1188 .1699 .6534
ALW-L -.0369 -.0728 -.1076 -1.3132 25
.0319 .0629 .0930 1.1352
BSY-L -.0172 -.0331 -.0479 -.2356 10
.0445 .0858 .1240 .6096
BSW-L ~.Ol43 -.0279 -.0409 -.2998 15
.0321 .0627 .0918 .6730
BLY-L -.0443 -.0843 -.1203 -.4530 7
.0521 .0991 .1415 .5327
.0378 .0731 .1060 .5625
CSY-L -.0216 -.0399 -.0555 -.l435 5
.0539 .0997 .1386 .3581
CSW-L -.0235 -.0438 -.0613 -.1719 5
.0582 .1084 .1518 .4257
CLY-L -.0588 -.1057 -.1432 -.2909 4
.0613 '.1102 .1492 .3033
CLW-L -.0613 -.1111 -.1516 -.3273 4
.0633 .1147 .1566 .3380
Trhe top quantity is the interest rate elasticity, and the
Ibottom line the economic activity variable elasticity. Half-
life is the time (in quarters) it takes for the elasticity to
reach at least one-half its steady-state value.
Model
ASY-L
ASW-L
ALY-L
ALW‘L
BSY-L
BSW-L
BLY-L
BLW-L
CSY-L
CSW-L
CLY-L
CLW-L
The top values are
RMCP
-0.0306
-1.4733
-0.0271
-1.0790
-0.0282
-0.9891
-0.0204
-0.6714
-0.0586
-1.7455
-0.0544
-1.6014
88
TABLE 5.8
ANNUAL MONEY DEMAND MODELS WITH LAGGED VARIABLES
RMLB
-0.1024
-2.5324
-o.0944
-1.8527
-0.1346
-3.1794
-0.1273
-2.5683
-0.1904
-4.0815
-0.1918
-3.9408
Y
0.3277
4.1586
0.3078
5.2593
0.1451
1.8544
.2161
.0589
#0
0.1471
1.5532
0.2161
3.5414
Y?
.3436
.0967
WC
.3219
.7385
(NO
.1221
.4279
P‘O
.2075
.2377
660
.1288
.3976
H0
0.2084
3.4044
the estimated coefficients,
Lag
0.2760
1.6652
0.1949
0.8032
0.3983
2.8129
0.3214
1.5192
0.4011
1.5570
0.3835
1.2919
0.4326
2.3335
0.3583
1.5736
0.3293
1.2932
0.3398
1.3027
0.1966
1.1051
0.2154
1.1854
2
Const R /SE
1.6097 .9808
3.7471 .0123
1.9151 .9729
3.1548 .0146
1.2307 .9861
3.0004 .0105
1.5176 .9778
2.5634 .0132
2.8968 .6353
1.9220 .0167
3.1885 .5891
1.9115 .0177
2.2736 .8096
2.0572 .0120
2.8320 .7510
2.1677 .0138
2.4881 .1347
1.7552 .0209
2.5460 .0985
1.7503 .0213
2.9073 .5937
3.1374 .0143
2.8673 .5750
3.0102 .0146
D.VJ.
1.5537
2.0671
2.1536
2.6712
1.2224
1.3007
2.0529
2.3594
1.6851
1.7075
2.3538
2.8383
the bottom values are the t-ratios.
89
dependent variables of the annual models are lower than in
the corresponding quarterly model. However when the steady
state elasticities for the annual models (given in Table
5.9) are examined, the elasticities are found to always be
at least one-half the steady—state value within one year,
and the steady state elasticities to be lower than the
quarterly steady-state elasticity. The use of annual data
- merely exacerbates the problem of low coefficients.
Thus the money demand models seem to imply a world where
a change in income or a weighted average of past income
had little initial effect on the money stock, and even in
those cases where the effect is sizable, the impact on the
money stock occurs slowly. The interest rate elasticity
also specifies a world where a change in the interest rate
does not have a sizable impact on the money stock.
It should be noted that the period over which the money
demand equation was estimated was a time of slow money stock
growth. The natural logarithm of the SA money stock in
.1947 was 4.72; in 1960, 4.95 while by 1970 it was 5.43.
TTLis situation can be observed in comparing the regressions
ftxr the nominal money stock for the 1947-1960 period, the
1947-1970 period, and the 1961-1970 period. Table 5.10
Shows low coefficients (and therefore low elasticities)
—¥
l4u. The annual money stock models were estimated with both
t1“; average of daily data for the entire year and the aver-
age of daily data for the two months around the first quar-
ter. There was little difference between the two sets of
eStimates .
90
TABLE 5.9
INTEREST AND INCOME ELASTICITY
OF ANNUAL MONEY DEMAND MODELS
Model B l a s t i c i t y Half
Impact Quarter 1 Quarter 2 Steady State Life
ASY-L -.0306 -.0390 -.0414 -.0423 1
.3277 .4181 .4431 .4526
ASW-L -.0271 -.0324 -.0334 -.0336 1
.3436 .4105 .4235 .4266
ALY-L -.1024 -.1432 -.1594 -.1702 1
.3078 .4304 .4792 .5116
ALW-L -.0944 -.1247 -.1345 -.1391 1
.3219 .4254 .4586 .4744
BSY-L -.0282 -.0395 -.0440 -.0471 l
.1451 .2033 .2266 .2423
BSW—L -.0204 -.0282 -.0312 -.0331 l
.1221 .1689 .1869 .1981
BLY-L -.1346 -.l928 -.2180 -.2372 1
.2161 .3096 .3500 .3809
BLW-L -.1273 -.l729 -.1893 -.1984 l
.2075 .2818 .3085 .3234
CSY-L -.0584 -.0779 -.0843 -.0874 l
.1471 .1955 .2115 .2193
CSW-L -.0544 -.0729 -.0792 -.0824 1
.1288 .1726 .1874 .1951
CLY—L -.l904 -.2278 -.2352 -.2370 l
.2161 .2586 .2669 .2690
.2084 .2533 .2630 .2656
The top quantity is the interest rate elasticity, and the
.bottom line the economic activity variable elasticity. Half—
life is the time (in quarters) it takes for the elasticity to
[reach at least one-half its steady-state value.
EstimationModel
Period
1947-
1960
1961-
1970
1947-
1970
ASY
ASH
ALY
ALW
ASY
ASW
ALY
ALW
ASY
ASW
ALY
ALW
RMCP
-0.0345
-3.4041
-0.0049
-0.5083
-0.0654
-3.8911
-0.0692
-4.3214
-0.0537
-2.9739
-0.0554
-2.9012
QUA
-O
-1
-0.
-1.
#0
NO
50
U10
91
TABLE 5.10
RTERLY NOMINAL MONEY DEMAND
MODEL
FITTED OVER THREE TIME PERIODS
RMLB Y
0.4271
23.9443
.0344 0.3982
.2302 18.6084
0293
1105
0.7151
30.7192
.1437 0.4987
.4681 15.3069
.1232
.4884
0.5151
22.9416
.1873 0.3147
.8724 10.6747
.1998
.0017
YP
0.3591
22.6158
0.3710
19.5880
0.7237
32.4332
0.5205
14.4815
0.5163
21.7542
0.3046
9.9442
Const
2.3616
24.0774
2.7760
32.4503
2.5442
24.8986
2.7374
32.7377
.5441
.1381
.50
0.5158
4.1126
.6291
.8670
\Dr—I
.5362
.4926
(DP
1.8543
15.3878
1.8636
14.7142
2.7750
21.0393
2.8288
20.7770
2
R /SE
.9700
.0153
.9667
.0161
.9643
.0167
.9673
.0160
.9866
.0171
.9879
.0162
.9877
.0164
.9865
.0172
.9678
.0356
.9648
.0372
.9718
.0333
.9696
.0345
D.W.
.2140
.1654
.1907
.1815
.2088
.3226
.2604
.2869
.0502
.0659
.0974
.0980
The top values are the estimated coefficients, the bottom values are the t-ratios.
92
for the early period, and considerably higher coefficients
for the latter period.15 This situation should go a long
way towards eXplaining the difference between the money
demand regressions and those of other studies.
5. Money supply: the Brunner model
The estimated regressions of the Brunner linear money
supply models in all cases had high R2 values, and in two
of the three cases (EBA and EBB) Durbin-Watson statistics
which rejected the hypothesis of statistically significant
autocorrelation. The results of these regressions are
shown in Table 5.11. The coefficients in some cases were
not significant. The best performing base concept (Model
EBA) was currency in circulation plus member bank's total
reserves, but even this model had an estimated coefficient
which was not significantly different than zero. Compen—
sating for reserves liberated through changes in the re-
quired reserve ratio (Model EBB) and subtracting out excess
reserves (Model EBC) did not improve the goodness-of-fit
statistics for the 1947-1960 estimation period.
These results are quite close to the results Brunner
obtained when he estimated his model. Brunner's results
15. This data will be used below in the Chow test for struc-
tural stability. The interest rate coefficients for the
1947-1970 and the 1961-1970 regressions were all significant
(while only one of the four interest rate coefficients for
the 1947-1960 regressions was significant). However the
sign of the long run interest rate coefficients was positive
in all cases.
93
mvm>.H
owam.a
momm.H
Nwmo.H
ommH.H
mmoH.H
mamm.
mmme.d
mmmm.H
.B.Q
Hmmm.
mhmm. om.c
mmvm.
memo. mm.o
mnmm.
sham. mm.o
vvmm.
Nmmm.
comm.
mwmm.
mmmo.
mmmm.
mvvm.m
rhea.
Nmmw.H
poem.
hhmv.a
wmmm.
mm\~m 9E
mavm.m
Hm¢N.om
mmoa.m
Nvmv.wm
mama.~
eevm.m~
omem.e
mmmm.m~
mmam.v
mmmh.hm
HNmN.v
momm.om
wwmv.m
onmn.maa
hmmm.m
momm.vm
Nmmh.m
bmmv.mm
umcoo
mm¢m.oa
Howh.o
mmmv.m
mNo>.o
momN.h
mmmm.o
movm.m~
Hmom-o
N¢NN.©H
maom.o
mohH.MH
mumm.o
mmq
oonm.al
N0MH.H¢I
¢mh¢.0I
Noam.NHI
mmhm.hl
mHom.mwNI
.H
mmhm.N
HmmN.mH
momm.m
ommw.NN
NHmm.m
mmmH.oN
mmmo.o
Nmm~.o
mmHN.o
mmmm.o
onmm.o
mmvm.a
mmmv.o
vam.m
mmav.~
oonm.MH
ommm.o
Hamm.¢
u
Hth.HI
ewmm.~¢l
mach.HI
meh.bml
mom0.HI
mmmm.mMI
homm.wl
mmo~.HmI
omhm.¢l
mawh.awr
avmm.¢l
mmhw.mwl
memo.vl
mmmv.moml
mwmb.v|
NHNH.mvHI
oamm.ml
vam.NmHI
x
Ammo: mmzzsmm mmB m0 wBZMHUHmmmOU QMBfiZHBmm
HH.m mam¢fi
vwmm.o
mome.o
Hmmh.H
momm.o
hmm¢.m
ommm.o
meH.o
mmHo.o
hamm.o
bvNH.o
hwmm.o
omva.o
ommm.m
oowv.H
Namm.HH
movm.~
ammo.vH
mHFN.N
mmmm
4QIUmH
4AImmm
éfllfimm
Alumm
Almmm
Qlfimm
0mm
mmm
0m0.0
NO
ma.mmqm<8
NN00.0
m000.0
mmw0.0
0000.0
H050.0
5000.0
0mv0.0
hm00.0
NhMH.N
m0a0.0
mmmH.N
m0H0.0
HQ
AMQOZ szHmB MSE m0 mBZNHUHmmMOU OmfidiHBmm
mowN.H
MNN0.0
0N00.0
50N0.0
mm0~.0l
mm00.0|
mvH0.H
hHN0.0
aux“
mm00.0l
0000.0I
HhN0.H
HmH0.0
HON0.H
mm~0.0
00m0.0
hMH0.0
Quid
000N.0I
0m00.0l
mmmm.m
m0v0.0
v0v~.v
vmm0.0
amha.m
mmv0.0
hQZfl
Almamma
momma
mmmn
Qme
AIWDXD
moxo
me
0x0
Hmpn
97
demand equations, but statistically significant autocorre-
lation still existed. The interest rate coefficient was
statistically significant only when the difference of the
interest rates was used as an eXplanatory variable. The
dummy variables in the equation where the interest rate co-
efficient is not constrained were also not significant.
The results obtained in all cases fell between Teigen's
estimates and Gibson's reestimation of the Teigen model.
This comparison, shown in Table 5.14, includes a reestimate
of the Teigen model for the 1947—1 to 1958-4 period—~the
period over which Gibson estimated the Teigen regression.
Gibson maintained that the difference between the Teigen
coefficients and his reestimated coefficients were due to
the difference in the data series used. Teigen used call
Report data which is for one day each quarter while Gibson
used quarterly averages of daily figures. 8 Data for the
reestimated regressions was the average of monthly averages
of daily figures of the two months that straddle the quar-
ters. This concept is quite close to Gibson's, and the
similarity of the reestimated coefficients to Gibson's co-
efficients would tend to confirm the hypothesis that the dif-
:ference between the various estimates of this model is due
t1) differences in the data series.
¥
123. Since banks almost always know when they must submit
‘tfle Call Report data, window dressing of the data can occur.
NCDr is the Call Report data for the same day each year.
MOreover neither December 31 or June 30, two common Call
Report dates, are typical days for the financial sector.
98
Hmom.
vmhv.a
0mm.H
vmmo.
Hmom.
0mmo.
mmom.
mooo.
mmwm.
own.
mm\ m
N
momm.vma
vm>0.H
mn¢¢.m¢a
VH50.H
vmmm.oma
moon.0
mmmm.mma
mmmm.0
umcou
mmhw.m
hom0.o
hmwa.h
vmma.0
ND
mmmH.N
mma0.0
0050.H
mmao.o
mmmm.m
NHH0.0
wmmv.m
mmm0.o
HQ
va.m mqmflB
mwha.m
mmvo.0
>0N0.N
0000.0
m¢v0.v
mmm0.0
mmh.¢
Hmh0.0
mazm
ammo: meHmB mmB m0 ZOmHm000.mm
ammo. ~0HH.O eemm.o
omao. mmmm.mm
ammo. mmmm.m
«men. mnvm.a omvm.mm noee.au
mmmm. mmmm.m mmmm.o mmem.ou
eomm.m mamm.m mmmv.a
mmmm. mmmm.mm mamm.a
memo. «Hem.ou emmm.0~
Noam. mvmm.Hu Hamm.o
ommo.m mmflm.oa
maem. mmmm.ae
mm\mm cam umcoo mmq mozm
0000.HI
0000H01
Hmh0.0
0BH0.0
hh0o.aa
500040!
hN00.0
0000.0
mmzm
H00N.0I
0H00.0|
>0h0.0
00H0.0
5000.01
00H0.0I
0000.0
H000.0
muzm
AMQOE zommHU mmB m0 mBZMHUHmmmOU DmfidzHEmm
mH.m mqm¢e
0000.0
0000.0
H000.H
H500.0
00h0.~
N0h0.0
0000.5H
0000.0
00HN.N
mmm0.0
0500.0N
0000.0
000>.H
0000.0
0005.0H
0000.0
Qmm
Alhmm.m
mmm.m
Almmmm
mmmm
H0002
101
As can be seen from Table 5.16, the reestimation of the
Gibson model was quite close to Gibson's results. The
coefficients which were insignificant in the reestimated
regressions also tended to be insignificant in Gibson's
regressions. The standard error of his regressions were
larger and his R2 smaller, but Gibson used NSA money stock
while the reestimated regressions used the SA money stock.
The incorporation of the reserves variable into the money
supply equation according to the t-ratios for this variable
was a significant addition, but this was not the case where
the interest difference term was replaced by the individual
interest rates. The Gibson model with the Teigen difference
of interest rates variable appears to be the most promising
forecasting model examined in this section.
B. EVALUATION OF PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE
While there is a wide range of possible prediction eval-
uation statistics, actually there is little difference be-
tween most of them. In this section will be described
those statistics which will be used to evaluate the predic-
tive performance of single equation models used to predict
the money stock.
1. General evaluation
The primary prediction evaluation statistic will continue
to be the root mean squared error for the entire forecast
iperiod and annually. The period of prediction will be up
102
A...
pHH-::IIIw
0000.0 0000.00 0000.0 0000.0I 000H.H 0000.00 0I00 I HI00
0000. 0000.00 0000.0 0H0~.0I 0000.0 0~H0.0 000 00000
0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0000.00 0I00 I HI00
0000. 0000.00 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 040 000
00.00 H000.m HOH0.H 0000.0 0000.0 0I00 I HI00
0000. 00.00 000.0 000.0 000.0 0009 acmbflw
00.HH 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 0I00 I HI00
0000. 00.00 000.0 0000.0 000.0 000.0 0009 cowbflw
ooflumm
\0onumz
mm\mm umcoo Ho 002% 0020 0020 £00 cofiumsflumm 00002
me02 ZOmmMO mmB m0 ZOmHmHEUHQmmm H42224
00.0 mqmfifi
0000
0000
000a
000a
000A
000a
0000
0000
0000
H000
Haw»
000a
000a
000a
000a
000a
0000
000a
000a
000a
H000
Ham»
113
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
QIZAU
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
01000
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0I300
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
Alwmo
0000.00
0000.00
0000.00
0000.00
0000.00
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
300
0000.00
0000.00
0000.00
0000.00
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
0000.0
MAO
Ac.u:oov o~.m mqm.o
mmmm.o
mmmm.o
Hbmm.a
Nmmm.o
Alxmm
mmo¢.mm
momH.mN
mmvo.ma
Hmvm.oa
memo.h
Hamm.v
mmhm.a
omwm.m
omno.¢
moam.m
0mm
mamm.~
moam.a
omvm.~
mmaw.a
mmmo.H
mmvH.H
Nmmv.o
vmha.o
mmvH.H
mmmm.o
Almmmm
hmmH.m
Hmmh.a
whom.v
ommo.m
mmvm.m
momo.b
NHHm.m
boom.w
«wa.m
mmvm.m
mmm
mmvh.ma
Hmbo.va
mwmh.m
mmmm.a
vmvm.v
hmhb.m
mm¢m.h
Mbom.m
mmmH.HH
NNmH.OH
mmm.m
mmvv.m
mvom.m
Navo.v
oomw.m
Nmmv.m
mvam.v
vmao.¢
mmhm.m
Hmao.m
mmmm.a
émm
HHNo.HH
hmmm.o
mmvm.m
mahm.m
vmmm.m
hmmm.m
mmHH.0H
smo>.HH
mvma.ma
mmvm.aa
xmm
mmmm.vm
mmhm.m
mmbm.m
mvwm.m
mmam.v
vhmm.m
vmvm.a
ommm.H
mmnv.H
onao.m
mmmo
mmom.NH
mmh>.b
momm.~
mmNH.v
on~.b
mhmb.h
mHvN.a
HMOF.OH
mwbm.HH
mmmm.0H
mmmm
vmnm.nm
hvmh.oa
mmmm.H
mmom.m
mvmv.b
mmmo.m
mmmo.a
wmmm.N
voma.m
vah.m
mDXQ
mem.HH
NhHh.m
omva.m
mHHv.h
homm.v
mmvc.m
wmmm.m
mhmv.N
momH.H
hmmn.o
Alumm
vvmm.mm
NNmH.mH
mhho.m
omhm.v
vmam.m
mmvm.¢
maam.~
mmma.m
mhhm.H
monv.d
me
NNNN.OH
wvom.b
moma.m
mvom.w
mHHH.v
vHH¢.v
mme.m
hmmo.m
mmmm.o
hhaw.o
Almmm
onav.hm
mmvm.m
mmmm.o
Nomm.m
comm.h
mmmm.m
«mam.o
wome.m
vmwa.~
omvw.m
DXD
mqmooz wqmmDm NMZOZ wqmmflmdbO m0 mOZ<2m0mmmm m>HBUHQmmm AdDZZé
NN.m mqm<8
osma
some
mead
head
mead
mama
¢mmH
mwma
mama
Hmma
Ham»
onma
mwma
mead
hwmd
mmmd
mwma
voma
mood
mama
mea
How»
116
TABLE 5.23
PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF THE TEIGEN MODEL
(1 quarter forecasts)
Statistic DXD DXS DXDS DSFS
RMSE 18.7372 19.2451 18.7875 17.5586
MAE 6.6685 7.1941 6.8172 6.2040
SE of MAE 17.7334 18.0773 17.7300 16.6353
billion, and in 1971 approximately $4 billion. No other
model displayed such erratic behavior. The standard
deviation of the MAE statistic confirms this observation
--it is about three times the value of the MAE.28
The Gibson alternative to the Teigen model outperformed
the Teigen model in the area of prediction. (In the
summary of the predictive performance of this model--Table
TABLE 5.24
PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF THE GIBSON MODEL
Model RMSE(1) MAE(l) RMSE(6) MAE(6)
FRSF 8.9383 8.1890
FRSF-L 1.5010 1.1715 7.5353 6.1326
FRX 9.4493 8.6965
FRX-L 1.8129 1.4588 8.9923 7.0113
F'RSF 10.1771 8.8360
F'RSF-L 1.4752 1.2118
i
28. Except in this case, the standard error of the MAE is
less than the actual value of the MAE itself.
117
5.24--the prime indicates a log-log version of the Gibson
29 In
model, D the Teigen structural shift dummy variable).
all cases the decade RMSE statistids and the MAE statistics
are quite low. Within the decade (Table 5.22), no strong
trend stood out. Predictive performance declined in 1970
as it did for most models, but not as radically as it did
in the Teigen model.
5. Adjustments of the constant term
In order to examine the effect on a forecast that a
constant adjustment term based on the residuals generated
by the regression has, three different constant adjustment
terms were studied. Table 5.25 tabulates the RMSE for the
first quarter forecasts of the 1962-1970 period when no
constant term was used, and when one of the three constant
adjustment terms described above was used.30 In all cases
the constant adjustment term reduced the RMSE over the entire
period. The larger the error without constant adjustment,
the greater the proportionate reduction of the RMSE when
the constant adjustment term is used. The constant adjust-
ment term also reduced the RMSE of models which included
29. Gibson included the Teigen dummy which marked the end of
the Korean War, but drOpped the dummy indicating the begin-
ning of the U.S. balance of payments problems. Gibson did
this because his estimation period was shorter. '
30. See p 104-105. The 1962-1970 period was used so that
RMSE statistics could also be computed for the triannual
periods 1962-1964, 1965-1967, and 1968-1970. These results
will be discussed in the next paragraph.
118
TABLE 5.25
PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF SELECTED MODELS
WITH CONSTANT ADJUSTMENT TERMS
(RMSE of 1 quarter forecasts)
Model . No Adjustment Adjustment Adjustment
Correction A . B C
ASY 9.2670 1.2569 1.7192 2.5782
ASW 9.6991 1.3688 1.9096 2.8481
ALY 10.4144 1.3647 1.8571 2.7130
ALW 10.0731 1.4192 1.9780 2.9523
ASY-L 2.2223 .8874 .9536 1.0123
ASW-L 1.6318 .9342 1.0069 1.0418
ALY-L 2.7690 .9664 1.0576 1.1367
ALW-L 2.3403 .9646 1.0517 1.2070
CSY-L 1.4758 .9155 1.0087 1.0332
CSW-L 1.4305 .9030 .9946 1.0287
CLY-L 3.5105 .9835 1.1097 1.2126
CLW-L 3.3847 .9769 1.1066 1.2260
EBA 4.2089 2.3467 2.2196 1.7566
EBB 6.0818 2.2883 2.1137 1.9122
EBC 11.8320 2.3325 2.5647 3.0148
EBA-L 4.6764 .9871 1.1036 1.1364
EBB-L 4.9675 .9887 1.1076 1.1541
EBC-L 5.6262 .0023 1.1206 1.2026
FRX 9.2581 2.6416 2.6044 2.7177
FRSF 8.4490 2.4738 2.3790 2.5218
F'RSF 8.7192 2.3507 2.3954 2.8458
FRX-L 1.5330 .9122 .9676 .9600
FRSF—L 1.3788 .9370 .9970 .9890
F'RSF-L 1.2968 .9535 1.0318 1.0298
119
a lagged dependent variable. The constant adjustment term
which worked best for all the money demand models was the
error of the previous period's prediction. The average of
the previous period, however, reduced the forecasting
error of two (EBA and EBB) of the three Brunner non-lagged
models better than did the previous period's residual. The
latter adjustment worked best in the remaining of the
Brunner models.
The triannual RMSE statistics showed that constant ad-
justment did not always improve the prediction performance
of the model. In many money demand models, especially
those where the lagged dependent variable was included in
the model, the RMSE for the 1965-1967 period was lower
when no adjustment term was used. This was not the case
in the Brunner models where in all cases constant adjust-
ment reduced the RMSE. The triannual data also showed that
the error terms for the 1968-1970 triannual period was the
highest of the three periods.
Longer forecasts increased the RMSE and lessened the
effect of the constant adjustment. However the relative
relationships described above held constant, i.e. if a
particular constant adjuStment term improved the predictive
performance of the model in a one quarter forecast; then
the predictive performance of the model in a six quarter
forecast would also be improved, but to a lesser degree.
This relationship held whether the constant term improved
or worsened the performance of the model. The superiority
120
of the single period adjustment term was not reported in
other studies where this approach was tried, but there is
no instrinsic reason why one particular constant adjustment
term should usually work better than another.
D . SUMMARY
In this chapter a set of money demand and money supply
models were estimated over the 1947-1960 period and then
used to forecast the 1961-1970 money stock. The estimated
coefficients of the various models were compared to esti-
mates made by others of similar models, and where the re-
sults were different an attempt was made to eXplain the
differences.
The principle observations of this chapter were as fol-
lows. (l) The Gibson models with the lagged dependent vari-
able predicted with lowest RMSE. The real money demand fun-
ction with the short-term interest rate and the lagged de-
pendent variable was a close runner-up. (2) The hypothesis
that structural shift occurred could be rejected by the Chow
test for the models mentioned above. But this hypothesis
was also rejected by the Chow test for a number of Brunner
money supply models which had inferior RMSE statistics.
(3) Adjustment of the constant term improved the predictive
performance of the models. The previous period's error
usually worked best. (4) The impact and steady state elas-
ticities of the money demand model were low relative to
other estimates of the money demand model.
CHAPTER VI
TWO-EQUATION MODELS
A. INTRODUCTION
In Chapter IV the predictive performance of naive and
mechanistic money stock models were examined while in
Chapter V the predictive performance of a number of single
equation money stock forecasting models were examined. In
this chapter the forecasting performance of some two-equa-
tion money stock forecasting models will be studie . The
selection of models to be examined is based to a great
extent on the results of the previous two chapters.
Using the convention of the previous chapter, each model
will consist of a money supply equation and a money demand
equation.1 It is unlikely, of course, that two equations
adequately specify the complexities of the money stock
determination process. The primary concern, however, is
the predictive ability of various money stock models, and
not this more basic question. The criteria of correct
specification and good forecasting ability are not in con-
flict, and ideally a model should have both characteristics.
If the equations estimated in Chapter V are incorrectly
1. See pp 36-37.
121
122
specified reduced-form equations, and more than one endo-
genous variable of the equation system is included in an
equation, unless the system is recursive, the equations
estimated in Chapter V are biased and inconsistent. There-
fore, to the extent that the two-equation models used in
this chapter reflect the actual structure of the money
stock determination process, the used of system estimation
techniques such as two-stage least squares (TSLS) will give
estimated equation parameters which are at least consistent.
The coefficients of the simultaneous equation models will
be estimated using the appropriate estimation techniques for
the 1947—2 to 1960-4 period.2 While statistics such as the
canonical correlation coefficient measure the goodness-of-
fit of the simultaneous system; if the structure of the
system changes, such statistics are of little value. In-
stead, consistent with the approach used in the earlier
chapters, the estimated models will be used to generate six
quarter simulations for the 1961-1 to 1972-2 period, and the
forecasting ability of the models will be evaluated based
on these simulations.
Two equation models imply that there are two endogenous
variables in the system. Obviously one of these variables
is the money stock. In this chapter the commercial paper
rate shall also be treated as the other endogenous
2. Only quarterly forecasts will be generated since the data
for many of the exogenous variables are available only in
quarterly form, e.g. GNP.
123
variable.3 While the primary focus of this study remains
the forecasting of the money stock, in the simultaneous
equation context, the forecasts of the other endogenous
variables can not be ignored. This situation will be
discussed in more detail in Section D of this chapter.
B . THE MODELS
Three different classes of money stock models will be
examined in this chapter. Each has a money supply equation
and, where warrented, three different money demand equa-
tions. That is, there may be as many as three versions of
a single model. The better performing versions of the var-
ious types of models which were examined in Chapter IV and
Chapter V will be considered as components for the models
to be examined in this chapter.
1. The money multiplier model
The supply side of the multiplier model is specified by
the money multiplier identity discussed and evaluated in
Chapter IV. There it was observed that the multiplier
identity which forecast with the lowest RMSE was the
3. The conventional second endogenous variable is the
interest rate, but prior to the Treasury-Federal Reserve
Accord, the Federal Reserve attempted to fix the rate at
a low level. This convention, then, results in speci-
fication error. But this difficulty would exist for
any variable the Federal Reserve viewed as a target
variable. Therefore, if the interest rate is used as-
an endogenous variable in the 1947-1951 period, the ques-
tion is not whether specification error exists, but how
serious the problem really is.
Wu._'i Ir:
124
no—change naive version of the multiplier.4 This version
of the multiplier, i.e. the value of the multiplier is
assumed to be fixed at its current value over the period
of the forecast, will be used in the multiplier model.
The demand side of this model will be Specified by the
nominal money demand equation with income, the commercial
paper rate, and the lagged dependent variable as explan-
atory variables. Since this equation is the only equation
which contains both endogenous variables--the money stock
and the commercial paper rate--the system is recursive,
and, therefore, ordinary least square estimates of the
coefficients of the money demand equation will be consis-
tent. Since the money supply equation is an identity, the
OLS coefficients of the money demand equation will also be
asymptotically efficient.
2. The Brunner-Meltzer model
The money supply equation in the second simultaneous
equation model will be the first of the Brunner-Meltzer
linear money supply equations.5 Since the predictive per-
formance of most models is improved by including a lagged
dependent variable in the model, the equation will also
include the lagged variable. However, as observed in
Chapter IV, the predictive performance of this particular
4. Equation 4.8, p 54.
5. Equation 3.10a, p 38.
">1
.‘hl‘o- s
i
1
125
equation did not improve when the lagged variable was
used.6 This situation suggests that the Brunner-Meltzer
money supply equation without the lagged variable could also
be considered as an alternative formulation of the model.
However as we shall bring out in Section D, since this
equation does not contain the endogenous interest rate
variable, and is, therefore, part of a recursive equation “1
system, both versions of this model can be evaluated with
data from only one version of the simultaneous system.
As with the multiplier model, the nominal money demand
model with the short-term interest rate, income, and the
lagged dependent variable will be used as the money demand
equation. From the recursive nature of the system, the OLS
estimates of the coefficients of the two equations will be
consistent, but asymptotically efficient only if the
variance-covariance matrix is diagonal.
3. The Teigen-Gibson models
Two versions of the Teigen-Gibson model will be used as
money supply equations. In both cases reserves adjusted for
reserve liberations due to changes in the required reserves
ratios and the difference between the commercial paper rate
6. See Table 5.21, p 114. The deterioration in predictive
performance was small. The RMSE for a one period forecast
was 4.1393 for the equation without the lagged variable,
5.3046 when the variable was included.
7. Kmenta, 1971, p 586. The correlation coefficient of the
estimated residuals of the two equations is 0.65.
126
and the Federal Reserve discount rate will be used as
explanatory variables. In one version of the model the
lagged dependent variable will be excluded, in the other it
will be included.
Three versions of the money demand equation will also be
used in the model. The first will be the demand equation
used in the above models. The second demand equation will_
use permanent income rather than GNP as an explanatory
variable while the third equation will eXpress all quantity
variables in real terms. The economic activity variable in
this last equation is real income. This set of demand
equations will be expanded to six by having three with
the lagged dependent variable, three without the lagged
variable.
Since both equations of this model contain both endogen-
ous variables, to obtain consistent estimates of the coeffi-
cients, a simultaneous equation estimation method must be
used. Therefore, the coefficients will be estimated by
means of TSLS and limited information single-equation (LISE)
estimation techniques. Full information estimation tech-
niques are ruled out because of the probability of equation
misspecification and the complexity of such estimation tech-
niques for non-linear equation systems.
4. The estimated models
In order to facilitate the discussion of these model, the
following discriptors for the various models shall be used.
127
The multiplier model will be referred to as Model A, and
the Brunner-Meltzer model as Model B. The Teigen-Gibson
models will have a two letter identifier. The first letter
C will identify the model with the lagged dependent vari-
able in the demand equation, andwithout the lagged vari-
albe in the supply equation. The letter D identifies those
models where both equations have the lagged variable, and
the letter E models with the lagged variable in the supply
equation but not in the demand equation. The second letter
specifies the money demand equation used in the model. A
represents the nominal money demand equation with income
as an explanatory variable, B represents the equation with
permanent income, and C represents the real money demand
equation.
The OLS regressions used for Models A and B have been
estimated in Chapter V. The estimated coefficients for the
money demand equation for both Model A and Model B can be
found in Table 6.1 as the OLS estimates for the demand
equation of Model CA8 while the Brunner-Meltzer money
supply coefficients are given in Table 5.11.9 The OLS,
TSLS, and LISE coefficients for the three C models are given
in Table 6.1. The demand equation coefficients for the D
models are the same as the C model coefficients since the
exogenous variables are the same for the two models. The
8. These coefficients are also given in Table 5.2,
Model ASY-L.
9. Equation EAA-L.
I“: g“ up 1"
a
k
128
mvvv.
Nmmo.
mnmm.
.3.D
vmhm.
mmmm.
ammo.
mmoo.
momm.
mwoo.
momm.
mmoo.
mmmm.
mm m
\N
omoo.
ammo.
mmoo.
vomm.
omoo.
homo.
m
mm\m
thm.o
HHmo.o
mmmv.o
mmmo.o
oowv.o
muoo.o
umcoo
Hmmm.a
mmHN.o
mmoo.m
mHNN.o
wmmm.m
mmnm.o
umcou
mmmm.ma
momm.o
mmhv.ha
moom.o
mmmo.mH
mmm¢.o
mmq
Hmsm.>a
hovm.o
momm.ma
wNmm.o
Nah¢.om
vam.o
man
momm.~
hmho.o
ovom.N
mmoo.o
vvwv.a
ammo.o
QM
momm.m
mwmo.o
mmmv.m
mhmo.o
mmmm.w
mmmo.o
M
mmom.mn
hamo.0I
mmmm.ml
m5mo.on
ammo.m1
omHo.0I
mozm
vomm.mt
wwwo.ou
hamm.mn
vmmo.OI
wmmm.ml
omHo.o1
mozm
mqmaoz mmHmmmIO mmB m0 mfizmHUHmmmoo
H.m mqméfi
mqu
mqmfi
mAO
mmHQ
mAmB
mQO
Gonumz
OMBdSHBmm
2 CH
ocmEmo
2 ca
ocmEmo
manmflum>
coflpmeflumm unwocmmmo
83 Iapow
VD IGPOW
129
mmhm.
comm.
momm.
.3.D
mmmw.
ovmm.
momm.
m¢NH.OH
mnma.
omvm.m
mamh.
vommum
mmmm.
mm\mm
mHNN.m
hmmm.o
mmvm.m
moom.
oomm.m
mmmm.
mm\mm
.
I
.t
wmmo.v
momm.ah
omvm.m
mmam.mm
mawm.m
mmmm.mm
uncou
Homm.v
tho.mo
vumm.m
mamm.v¢
mamm.m
mmmm.mm
#mcou
a
O N. 1'31. lic‘li
mHmN.N
ommm.m
omvm.m
vamm.m
mhvamN
vvvo.m
Amm
mmmm.m
Hmmb.N
mohm.ma
mwmv.v
mhvm.mm
vevo.m
9mm
A©.ucoov H.m
moms.“
mmmm.om
Hmmm.m
omhh.ha
mmmv.H
mmmm.H
mmzm
Mbhm.m
mvmm.mm
mmam.N
hvmo.m
momv.H
mmmm.H
mazm
mqm<8
mmHA
mAmB
qu
mmHA
mama
mQO
Begum:
mammsm
2
mammsm
manmfium>
soflumswumm usmoammmo
DD IQPOW
83 IGPOW
130
ammo.
hqvm.
momm.
.3.Q
momm.
homo.
comm.
mmmm.m
«mom.
mHoN.v
comm.
oomm.m
mmmm.
m m
m\~
mmoo.
vase.
omoo.
mmhm.
vmoo.
mmmo.
mm\mm
Hmoh.v
«www.mo
mmmm.h
mvmv.mv
mamm.m
mmmm.om
pmcou
oamo.o Hamm.va
vmmo.o mhom.o
mmam.o mmHH.mH
mhao.o ooom.o
omnn.a mamm.ha
mmmv.o mmvm.o
umcoo mod
omma.m
mmmm.m
mmwm.m
«mom.v
mhvw.mm
vvvo.m
amm
onma.o
mnoo.o
oaav.o
mmao.o
mmmm.m
mmmo.o
m\w
mmwm.m
mwhv.mm
momm.N
vmom.ma
momv.H
mmmm.H
mozm
moam.on
mmoo.o:
Nomv.OI
mooo.ol
vaom.MI
oHNo.oI
muzm
Ao.ucoov H.o mamas
mmHA
mama
mAO
mmHA
mAmB
mAO
eonpmz
mammsm
m\z :H
panama
manmflum>
coaumaflumm usmocmmmo
V3 Iapow
DD IGPOW
131
OLS, TSLS, and the LISE estimates for the money supply
equations, however, are given in Table 6.2. Likewise the
estimates for the coefficients of the money demand equation
without the lagged variable (Model B) are given in Table
6.3. The dependent variable of the money demand equation
of the C, D, and E models is the logarithm of the money
stock.10 The dependent variable of the money supply
equation, the Teigen-Gibson money supply function, is the
nominal money stock.
The coefficients of the different estimates of the money
demand equations in models CA, CB, DA, and DB are quite
close whether estimated by OLS, TSLS, or LISE; and the
increase in the standard error for these regressions when
the coefficients are estimated by TSLS or LISE is small.
The difference between the OLS estimates and the TSLS and
LISE estimates of demand equations for Model CC and DC is
striking. But the coefficients which change the most have
t-ratios of above 2.0 when estimated by OLS, and less than
0.6 when estimated by TSLS or LISE. The decrease in the
standard error is slight when the demand equation is not
estimated by OLS.
The coefficients for the demand equations without the
lagged variable, however are affected by the estimation
method used. The coefficients for the two variables are
10. For Models CA, CB, DA, DB, EA, and EB it is the loga-
rithm of the nominal money stock, for Model CC, DC, and
EC it is the logarithm of the real money stock.
“flunk-)mm 6' _ I.
,.
I
I
132
mmmm.
ammo.
momm.
boon.
ooow.
movm.
omvo.
.3.D
.H.o magma CH oasom mm mEMm on» mum mucofloflmmmoo :oflumsvm ocmfimo mmcofi one
ovvv.H
mmmm.
moom.
ommm.
Hoao.H
mamm.
Hmow.
ovmm.
hva.H
hmmm.
mmoa.a
Nomm.
Noon.
Nmmm.
mm m
\N
ommo.m
vmwh.oa
mmmn.a
mmmh.m
mmvm.~
Nmmo.h
oovm.m
mnmm.m
hoaw.m
wmon.m
momm.m
vomm.h
mhvm.a
Nmom.m
umcou
ommm.m
hmmm.o
HHmo.oH
mmmm.o
mom¢.oH
Nth.o
boon.ma
mvmm.o
oomm.NH
momw.o
mmma.va
voom.o
omvm.mm
mmmm.o
mod
ohvo.a
momo.o
mmmo.m
mhh¢.o
omHo.m
Hmam.o
vaH.N
mmov.o
momm.H
mmom.o
momm.H
mowm.o
ovam.m
mmmv.o
Amm
Nomm.H
Hasm.m mqu
mmos.o .
ssao.a mama on
mmmo.a
momm.H mmHa
ssmm.o
smmm.o mama mo
mmms.a
mmms.~ mqu
mvmm.a
momm.~ mama
sows.a-
mmsm.o- moo am
gonna:
mozm COflngflumm Homo:
mAWQOZ mmHmmmIQ HEB m0
N.o mqmflB
mZOHfidadm MammDm NMZOZ mmB m0 mBZmHUHmmMOU OMB.m «www.ma mmmm.m|
mmmm. oomm. momm.a oaom.o ommo.ou mums
mmao. vsno.vm mvvm.mm avov.mn
ovam. oonm. oaom.m anmv.o memo.on mqo 4m
oonumz
.3.o mm\mm umcoo m» Am\w Hoe w mozm nodumefiumm Howe:
mamaoz mmHmmmlm mmB ho
mZOHB
0
(6.1a) ln RMCP = -‘_‘
ID)
82 3
-T1nY-_lnM
1 B1 1
The other two versions of the money demand equations for
MOdel C were rewritten with the apprOpriate changes. The
transformation shown in Equation 6.1a was also used for the
simulations of Model A and Model B.
Since we have both TSLS and LISE estimates of the model,
the question arises as to which should be used for fore-
casting. In all cases, the standard error of estimate was
lower for the TSLS regressions. This suggests the use of
the TSLS coefficients. Moreover Theil maintains that when
a difference in the values of the estimated coefficients
is observed, that the TSLS estimates should be used in pre-
ference to the LISE. [Theil, 1971, p 532]. The TSLS
coefficients, therefore, will be used in the forecasting
equations.
D. THE RESULTS
1. Forecasting the money stock with recursive models
The results of the multiplier model (Model A) and the
Brunner-Meltzer model (Model B) are identical to that of
137
the single equation models.l3 Since there is no lagged
term in the multiplier model, predictive ability does not
decline as the forecasting period is lengthened.l4 The
lagged term, however, is included in the Brunner-Meltzer
equation so that forecasts longer than one quarter can be
generated.
The overall RMSE statistics for one through six quarter
forecasts for these two models are given in Table 6.4 while
the mean percent absolute error data is given in Table 6.6.
The error associated with forecasting the money stock in
recursive models is the same as for the single equation
models with the same endogenous variables. Therefore the
ability to forecast the money stock by recursive models can
be determined by examining the predictive performance of
the apprOpriate single equation models.15
2. Forecasting the money stock with non-recusrive models
Unlike Models A and B, the Teigen-Gibson money demand
Inodels are not recursive, and so the money stock and the
13. For Model B, see Table 5.21. The RMSE statistics for
the multiplier model are a bit different since they were
computed over the slightly different time period. Compari-
son of the annual RMSE data, however, shows the identity
of the results.
14. When a lagged term is not included in an ex post fore-
casting model, all forecasts are essentially one period
forecasts. See p 103.
15. For example, the predictive performance of the not-
lagged first Brunner model can be found in Table 5.11,
Model EBA.
138
TABLE 6.4
PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF TWO-EQUATION MODELS
OF THE MONEY STOCK
Model Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter
1 2 3 4 5 6
A 2.2380 2.2245 2.2294 2.2270 2.2489 2.2292
B 5.3047 10.1477 14.3957 18.1238 21.6497 24.9463
CA 2.6365 4.9729 6.8511 8.3591 9.7970 11.1019
CB 3.1680 6.0131 8.3720 10.3227 12.1529 13.8141
CC 1.9134 3.6563 5.1022 6.3747 7.6729 9.0093
DA 2.4253 4.6765 6.5591 8.1445 9.7159 11.2000
DB 2.0239 3.9690 5.6142 7.0363 _8.5071 9.9419
DC 1.9200 3.4675 4.7988 5.8844 6.9840 8.1252
EA 5.3809 8.6880 10.6554 11.8599 12.8755 13.7668
EB 3.6542 6.7601 ' 9.0871 11.0575 12.7402 14.2245
EC 3.2573 5.8414 7.7314 9.0897 10.2491 11.2196
TABLE 6.5
PREDICTIVE PERFORMANCE OF TWO-EQUATION MODELS
OF THE INTEREST RATE
Model Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter
1 2 3 4 5 6
A 4.4144 6.6897 6.6651 6.6306 6.6508 6.6743
B 9.5640 10.0182 10.3759 10.5826 10.9316 11.3324
CA 0.5427 0.5730 0.5856 0.6088 0.6701 0.6990
CB 0.7537 0.8306 0.9070 0.9856 1.0742 1.1226
CC 0.5174 0.5664 0.5854 0.6256 0.6971 0.7410
DA 0.6010 0.6156 0.6145 0.6235 0.6836 0.7137
DB 0.5629 0.5970 0.6182 0.6541 0.7502 0.8043
DC 2.1404 1.9838 1.9504 1.9972 2.0446 2.0589
EA 1.7657 1.1202 0.8126 0.7036 0.7318 0.7642
EB 2.2249 1.8731 1.5012 1.1862 0.9570 0.8187
EC 1.5824 1.2159 0.9741 0.8668 0.9290 1.0093
139
TABLE 6.6
COMPARISON OF THE PREDICTION
AND THE INTEREST RATE
OF THE MONEY STOCK
(Mean Percent Absolute Error of 1 to 6 quarter forecasts)
Model Var-
ible
A M
RMCP
B M
RMCP
CA M
RMCP
CB M
RMCP
CC M
RMCP
DA M
RMCP
DB M
RMCP
DC M
RMCP
EA M
RMCP
EB M
RMCP
Ex: M
RMCP
Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter
1
1.1064
2.4016
1.0942
40.4304
1.2435
62.6529
0.8220
36.1223
0.9594
41.3806
0.8170
34.7272
0.8100
101.0370
- 2.0959
129.5495
1.4267
1.3672
2
1.0855
4.5519
1.9787
41.9595
2.3235
74.8008
1.5581
39.7880
1.7912
42.6238
1.5529
37.0629
1.4396
92.5165
3.2785
80.2648
2.5643
2.4038
3
1.0937
6.4459
2.6774
43.5137
3.2548
84.1521
2.1977
42.7585
2.4899
42.5931
2.1917
39.3253
2.0023
90.5429
3.9573
58.8731
3.4482
l60.6466132.6093103.5653
3.1593
121.0287 92.2134 71.3931
4
1.0805
8.1175
3.2316
45.7172
4.0475
89.2568
2.7478
47.4642
3.0973
43.7603
2.7547
42.8063
2.4070
5
1.0850
9.6476
3.7246
49.5123
4.7703
95.4925
3.3071
51.8774
3.6489
47.6267
3.2930
48.6164
2.8334
6
0.0545
341.0984486.3145482.4153472.3153477.l770483.5724
11.0543
846.2194887.4291922.6329949.8376983.91101018.660
51.7881
5.4011
98.2608
3.8625
56.9353
4.1768
50.2393
3.8307
52.8889
4.4933
94.9068100.1531101.8735
4.3761
50.7998
4.1110
79.1343
3.6926
62.1599
4.7017
52.4478
4.6970
62.6211
4.1328
62.2277
4.9634
54.6762
5.1871
54.4618
4.4737
64.4639
140
interest rate are jointly determined. The forecast quan-
tities, therefore, will be differerent than the single
equation forecasts. Ignoring the inclusion or exclusion
of the lagged variable for a moment, the best performing
models in general had the real money demand equation.16 In
two cases the models-with the money demand equation with
permanent income as an explanatory variable were ranked
second.17 The model with the lowest RMSE was Model DC
where both equations had lagged variables and the demand
equation was in real terms.18
The incorporation of the lagged dependent variable in a
single equation model usually reduced the forecasting error
for short forecasts. This gain in forecasting performance
with the lagged variable, however, deteriorated as the
forecast was lengthened since the model now included a
forecast independent variable: the lagged variable. This
caused error buildup to occur as the period of the fore-
cast increased. Both of the equations in the D series
models have lagged variables while the C series models only
the money demand equations have a lagged variable. In the
E series it is the money supply equations models which have
the lagged variable. Single equation models without the
16. Models CC, DC, and EC.
17. Models DB and EB.
18. In the first quarter Model CC had a lower RMSE, but
this was by a very small margin.
141
lagged variable tend to have a relatively high, but con-
stant error term over the forecast period while single
equation models with the lagged variable tend to have an
initially low error which builds as the forecast is ex-
tended. To what extent does this pattern carry over to
the simultaneous equation models?
The data presented in Tables 6.4 show the D series
models which have lagged dependent variables in both equa-
tions forecasting with a lower RMSE than models where at
least one equation lacks the lagged variable.19 Moreover
error buildup occurs in all the forecasts, and with a
pattern and magnitude similar to that of the single equa-
20 The series with the highest overall RMSE
tion models.
statistics of the non-recursive models was the E series
models which had the demand equation without the lagged
variable.
The annual RMSE statistics for the C, D, and E series
models are given in Table 6.5. These statistics reveal that
part of the lower overall RMSE associated with the D series
models is due to the fact that the annual RMSE statistics
for these models deteriorate less in the late 1960's than
19. The exceptions to this statement are the one-quarter
forecasts of Model CC and the six quarter forecasts of Model
CA. The difference in RMSE in each of these cases was
small.
20. See Table 5.19 for the single equation money demand RMSE
statistics. The RMSE statistics for the Teigen-Gibson model
‘with the lagged variable over the six quarters are 1.8129,
3.5459, 5.0301, 6.3308, 7.6775, and 8.9922.
142
do those of other models. In the early 1960's other models
frequently outperformed the D series models, but around
1967 when the quality of the 6 quarter forecasts declined,
except for Model CA, the decline was less for the D series
models.
Some of the RMSE statistics of the single equation model
are given in Table 6.5 in order to compare the relative
forecasting power of one and two equation models. Exam-
ination of the overall RMSE statistics show that except
for Model DC, the RMSE for the six—quarter forecast of the
Teigen-Gibson model with lagged variables was lower than
any of the other two-equation models. The real money de-
mand equation also had a lower RMSE than any of the two
equation models. When two superior forecasting models are
combined to make a two-equation forecasting model, that
model is characterized by low RMSE statistics although in
these cases the predictive performance of the single equa-
tion model is superior.21 The RMSE statistics for the two
equation model tends to be the average of the two individual
equation models.
21. For example, the RMSE statistics for Models FRD—L and
.ASW-L are close--8.9922 and 9.8346; but when combined to
become Model DB, the RMSE is slightly higher--9.94l4. This,
of course, would be expected unless there were a strong
negative covariance between the error terms of the two
equations.
143
3. Forecasting the interest rate
While forecasting the interest rate is not a matter of
concern in this study, nevertheless it may be worthwhile
to examine these predictions. Table 6.7 gives the RMSE
statistics for six quarter forecasts of the interest rate.
The RMSE statistics for Models A and B are high. This
situation follows from the recursive nature of the system:
the money stock is first forecast, and only then is the
interest rate forecast.
Since the average value of the interest rate is different
from the average value of the money stock, a more realistic
statistic to examine is the mean percent absolute error
(MPAE)for both the money stock and the interest rate fore-
cast. These statistics are given in Table 6.6. They bring
out dramatically the inferior quality of the recursive model
forecasts of the interest rate. This table, however, also
shows that the interest rate forecasts of the non-recursive
simultaneous equations models are inferior to that of the
forecasts of the money stockJ The forecasting performance
over the six quarters remained constant for the D series
models, deteriorated over the forecast period for the C
series models, and actually improved over the forecast
period for the E series models. It appears, therefore,
that the money demand equation contributed more to the
determination of the interest rate than the money supply
144
omHN.HH
omHN.HH
mmom.ha
moom.mH
vhmm.va
hmhh.b
ommo.N
hwhm.m
momv.o
onmm.m
ommm.m
Um
m¢~N.¢H
omo¢.hm
«Nam.mm
Hamo.ma
mono.oa
oomH.m
vmmm.~
vmav.m
mvmm.o
mmmm.~
Hoao.m
mm
mooh.ma
whom.om
momm.mm
hmmo.ha
mmmm.¢a
Noom.o
vovm.H
omhm.H
ONNN.H
oovo.m
oomm.m
ém
NmNH.m
NmNH.m
Nmoo.o
mhmo.m
mmom.ma
hmom.m
mamm.¢
mnmm.o
omom.v
momo.m
hmmm.o
0Q
oavm.m
wovo.md
«www.mH
mmmo.NH
mmov.ma
mmmH.h
coma.m
Hmvh.m
whoH.H
omon.a
momo.m
ma
ooom.HH
mmho.HN
oavm.mH
mmmh.ma
mmvo.va
boom.h
mmhm.H
vmmv.m
ohom.c
momb.H
mamm.m
fin
mmoo.m
ONHN.oH
hmoo.oa
NHbv.o
mvov.mH
mooo.m
Noom.¢
mmmm.h
mono.v
mmmm.~
Hooo.o
UU
AmummomHOM umUHMDW o mo Mmzmv
Hva.MH
Nmmh.mm
omov.m~
hHmo.mH
Hmmn.bH
moom.m
mahm.v
mmba.o
hobo.m
Hmvo.H
Nmoo.m
m0
mAMQOZ Dmeumqmm m0 @0242m0mmmm m>HBUHDmmm AdDZZd
h.o mamde
mHOH.HH
HHHm.om
mamm.ma
ommo.MH
Hmoa.mH
hmmo.o
moom.o
Namo.m
mamb.o
Hove.m
omah.m
flu
omlao
onma
momH
moma
homa
ooma
moma
vomH
momH
momH
HomH
uwmw
145
equation.
The larger forecasting error for the interest rate can be
explained by the fact that the interest rate series itself
is a more volatile series than the money stock series.
Moreover these equations were not conceived as having the
interest rate as the endogenous variable.
0'
D . SUMMARY
The results of this chapter can be summarized very
briefly. (1). The money stock forecasting error in a two-
equation recursive system will be the same as for the
single equation model without the system's other endogenous
variable. (2) The forecasting error of a model where the
two endogenous variables are jointly determined, the money
stock error statistic will tend to be the average of the
results of the two single equation models.23 (3). The
models which were used in this study were poor forecasters
of the interest rate.
22. In order for error buildup to occur in a model over the
forecast period, the lagged version of the model must be
used. Error build-up occurred when lagged versions of the
Inoney demand equations were used, and the money supply
equations had no lagged term (the C series models), and
the opposite phenomenon occurred when the not-lagged version
of the money demand equation and the lagged version of the
money supply equations were used.
23. See footnote 18 for a caveat on this observation.
CHAPTER VII
CONCLUSION
This chapter is an outline of the principle results of
this study. Because of the nature of the study, emphasis
will be on the preceeding three chapters. Of immediate
interest, of course, is the answer to the question: Which
of the money stock models considered in this study fore-
cast best? In addition, the various means of improving
predictive performance and the evaluation of predictive
performance will also be discussed in this chapter.
A. FORECASTING PERFORMANCE
The models which forecast best in this study were two
mechanistic models: the autoregressive seasonally adjusted
money stock model and the no-change money multiplier
model.1 The autoregressive model had the lowest RMSE
statistic for short forecasts while the multiplier model
had the lowest RMSE statistic for longer forecasts. The
predictive performance of the autoregressive multiplier
1. Since the monetary base must be forecast when using the
Inultiplier models, they are not true mechanistic models.
It may, in fact, be almost as difficult to forecast the
jbase as it is to forecast the money stock. The value of
-the multiplier itself, however, is forecast by means of
a mechanistic model .
146
147
model was also quite respectable, but examination of the
estimated coefficients for this model show that it is
essentially a no-change model.
Three models are next in terms of forecasting performance.
Two are single-equation real money demand models with the
lagged dependent variable, the short-term interest rate, and
either income or permanent income.3 The other mOdel is the
single-equation Gibson model with the lagged dependent
variable.4 The RMSE statistics for these models were quite
close for the short forecasts, but the real money demand
models had better prediction statistics than the Gibson
models in the longer forecasts. The next level of predic-
tive performance would include many of the other money de-
mand equations with the lagged variable. Also included
in such a list would be the better performing of the two-
equation forecasting models.
B. IMPROVEMENT OF FORECASTING PERFORMANCE
Since time series data were used in this study, the
improvement of forecasting performance which occurred when
a lagged variable was included in the model was not
2. See Equation 4.11 and Equation 4.14.
3. The real money demand model with permanent income as the
(explanatory variable had a slightly lower RMSE over the
forecast interval.
.4. The Gibson model with the interest coefficient not con-
srtrained to be equal in magnitude had somewhat lower RMSE
sytatistics than did the model with the constrained interest
rates.
148
unexpected. Only once did forecasting performance of
single-equation models deteriorate when such a variable
was added.5 The Gibson model was one example where the
improvement in predictive ability of a model was quite
marked.
One way of correcting for the temporal interrelatedness
of the variables is to include the lagged variable in the
model; another way is correcting for first-order auto-
correlation. When the money demand equations without
1agged variables were corrected for first-order autocor-
relation, the RMSE of a forecast was reduced even more than
when the lagged variable was included in the equations.
When the money demand equations with the lagged terms
were corrected for autocorrelation, the RMSE was also
usually reduced but by a smaller proportion.
While no attempt was made in this study to use or
evaluate judgmental corrections of the constant term,
various mechanical constant adjustment techniques were
used, all of which used the residual from the forecast of
the previous period. The RMSE in most cases was reduced
when these adjustments were made. The RMSE of models with-
out the lagged term, when adjusted, was lower than that of
the lagged model not adjusted. Adjustment of the lagged
model, however, also improved forecasting performance.
5. This case was the first Brunner-Meltzer model,
Equation 3.10a.
149
The best performing constant adjustment term in this study
was the previous period's residual.
C. TWO-EQUATION MODELS
Two types of the two-equation forecasting models, re-.
cursive and non-recursive, were examined. When the system
was recursive, the money stock RMSE statistics were the
same as the statistics for the one equation model which
contained both endogenous variables. The other equation
would forecast the other endogenous variable which in
this case was the interest rate. The RMSE statistics for
.the interest variable were quite high.
The non-recursive two-equation models, where both endo-
genous variables were in both equations, consisted of the
Gibson equation and three forms of the money demand
equation. The models with the real money demand equation
with the lagged dependent variable and the Gibson model
with or without the lagged variable had the lowest RMSE.6
These models, however, had higher RMSE's than did the
better single equation models. Forecasts of the interest
rate by the non-recursive models, while better than those
by the recursive models, still had high RMSE statistics.
Comparison of the coefficients estimated by means of
OLS and TSLS reveals that the two nominal money demand
equations with a lagged variable were insenstive to
6. The Gibson equation with the lagged variable had a
slightly lower RMSE over most of the forecast period.
150
estimation model. But the estimated coefficients of the
Gibson model and the real money demand model whether or
not the models include a lagged variable were quite
sensitive to estimation method. This was also the situation
for the nominal demand models without the lagged variable.
In practicially all cases for these models, the TSLS
estimates differed from the OLS estimates, and the LISE
estimates differed even more so. The sensitivity of the
lagged Gibson equation to the method of estimation was
particularly interesting in light of the forecasting
performance of the single-equation Gibson models.
D. EVALUATION OF PREDICTIONS
The RMSE statistic was the main prediction evaluation
statistic used in this study. When it was necessary to
compare the forecasts of different variables, the mean
percent absolute error statistic was used. Little if any-
thing seemed to be gained by using other prediction evalu-
ation statistics. Regressions of the predicted quantity
on the actual quantity showed themselves incapable of being
a measure of forecasting performance. Only the standard
error of estimate appeared to be of interest, but it re-
vealed nothing that was not already revealed in a more
meaningful fashion by the RMSE statistic.
Both the mechanistic and the one-equation models were
tested to determine whether a significant structural
shift occurred between 1947-1960 and 1961-1970. The
151
hypothesis that no structural shift occurred was rejected
for four of the five mechanistic models examined. The
exception was the no-change multiplier model which for
forecasts of over six months was the best performing mech—
anistic model. Among the single equation models, the
hypothesis that structural shift had not occurred could be
rejected for only two models without a lagged dependent
variable: the first Brunner-Meltzer model and the Teigen
model. Inclusion of the lagged term in the equations im-
proved the structural stability of the models, and in-
creased the number of models for which the hypothesis
could be rejected. Included in a listing of these models
would be the money demand models and the lagged Gibson
model. It should also be noted that the Teigen model,
with and without the lagged dependent variable, did not
exhibit significant structural shift, but also had the
worst prediction record of the single equation models
examined. Structural stability, therefore, is not a suf-
ficient condition nor, based on the evidence from this
study, a necessary condition for forecasting with low RMSE.
E. INCOME AND INTEREST ELASTICITIES
The coefficients of the money demand equations indicated
low impact and steady state income and interest elasti-
cities.7 The elasticities derived from TSLS estimates of
7. In only one case were the elasticities above 1.0, and
then it took 25 quarters for the elasticities to reach
152
the money demand equations with the lagged dependent vari-
able were close to those derived from OLS estimates, but
TSLS estimates of the demand equations without the lagged
variables indicated elasticities of somewhat greater
magnitude. Compared to other studies, however, the values
of both the interest and income elasticities remained low.
F. SUMMARY
The results of this study can be seen as presenting a
challenge to the econometric model builder. Two mechan-
istic models forecast with lower forecasting error than
any of the one- or two-equation economic models. It
should be noted, however, that the best performing eco-
nomic models forecast as well as the autoregressive money
stock model in the longer forecasts while the monetary
base, the exogenous variable in the no-change multiplier
model, may itself be quite difficult to forecast. More-
over, the strong time trend of the money stock data series
may help explain the high level of performance of the
mechanistic models, and indicate why such models provide
such a tough performance standard for the economic models.
one-half its steady-state value.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Andersen, 1968. Andersen, Leonall C., and Jordan, Jerry L.
"The monetary base--explanation and analytical use."
St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank Buiieiin 50(August
1968): 7—11. -
Ando, 1972. Ando, Albert; Modigliani, Franco; and Rasche,
Robert. "Equations and definitions of variables for
the FRB—MIT—Penn econometric model, November 1969."
Hickman, 1972, pp 543-598.
Bassie, 1955. Bassie, V. Lewis. "Recent develOpments in
short-term forecasting." Conference, 1955, pp 7-42.
Boughton, 1969. Boughton, James, M.; Brau, Edward H.;
Nayor, Thomas H.; and Yohe, William P. "A policy
model of the United States monetary sector." Southenn
Economic Jounnai 35(1969): 333-346.
Box, 1970. Box, George E. P., and Jenkins, Gwilym M. Time
SenieA Anaiybib, Fonecaoiing and Coninoi. San Fran-
cisco: Holden-Day, 1970.
Brunner, 1961. Brunner, Karl. "A schema for the supply
theory of money." Iniennaiionai Economic Review
2(1961): 79-109.
Brunner, 1964. Brunner, Karl, and Meltzer, Allan H. "Some
further investigations of demand and supply functions
for money." Jouhnai 06 Finance 19(1964): 2401233.
Brunner, 1966. Brunner, Karl, and Meltzer, Allan H. "A
credit market theory of the money supply and an ex-
planation of two puzzles in U. S. monetary policy."
Tullio Bagiotti, ed, ficayb in honoun 06 Manco Fanno,
Vol II: Inveoiigaiionb in Economic Theony and Metho-
doiogy. Padova: Edizioni Cedam, 1966. pp 151-176.
Burger, 1972. Burger, Albert E., "Money stock control."
St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank Bulletin 54(October
1972): 10-18.
Chow, 1960. Chow, Gregory C. "Tests of equality between
sets of coefficients in two linear regressions,"
Economeiaica 28(1960): 591-605.
154
155
Chow, 1966. Chow, Gregory C. "On the long-run and short-
run demand for money." Joannal 06 Political Economy
74(1966): 111-131.
Christ, 1956. ChriSt, Carl F. "Aggregate economic models."
Amenican Economic Review 46(1956): 385-408.
Christ, 1971. Christ, Carl F. "Econometric models of the
financial sector." Joannal 06 Money, Cnedit and
Banking 3(1971): 419-449.
Cole, 1969. Cole, Rosanne. Ennonb in pnouibional eAtimateA
05 gnoAA national pnoduct. New York: National Bureau
of Economic Research, 1969.
Conference, 1955. Conference on Research in Income and
Wealth. Shott-tenm economic fionecabting, Studies in
Income and Wealth, Vol 17. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1955.
COOper, 1972. COOper, Ronald L. "The predictive perfor-
mance of quarterly econometric models of the United
States," Hickman, 1972, pp 8.3-926.
deLeeuw, 1965. deLeeuw, Frank. "A model of financial
behavior." Duesenberrry, 1965, pp 464-530.
deLeeuw, 1968. deLeeuw, Frank, and Gramlich, Edward.
"The Federal Reserve-MIT econometric model." Federal
Reserve Bulletin 54(1968): 11-40.
deLeeuw, 1969. DeLeeuw, Frank. "A condensed model of
financial behavior." Duesenberry, J.S.; Fromm, G.;
Klein, L. R.; and Kuh, E.; ed., The Bnoohingb Model:
Aome (unthen nebultb. Chicago: Rank-McNally, 1969.
pp 269-315.
Dickson, 1972. Dickson, Harold D., and Starleaf, Dennis R.
"Polynomial distributed lag structure in the demand
function for money." Jounnal 06 Finance 27(1972):
1035-1043. '
Diller, 1969. Diller, Stanley, "Expectations in the term
structure of interest rates." Mincer, 1969, pp 112-
166.
Duesenberry, 1965. Duesenberry, James 5.; Fromm, Gary;
Klein, Lawrence R.; and Kuh, E., ed. The Bnoohingb
Quantenly Econometnic Model 06 the United StateA.
Chicago: Rand McNally, 1965.
156
Evans, 1968. Evans, Michael K., and Klein, Lawrence R.
The Whahton Economethic Foaecasting Model. Second
enlarged edition; Philadelphia: Economics Research
Unit, University of Pennsylvania, 1968.
Evans, 1969. Evans, Michael K. Machoeconomic activity,
theony, fiohecasting, and conthol. New York: Harper
and Row, 1969.
Evans, 1972. Evans, Michael K.; Haitovsky, Yoel; and
Treyz, George I. assisted by Su, Vincent. "An
analysis of the forecasting properties of the U. S.
econometric models." Hickman, 1972, pp 949-1139.
Feige, 1967. Feige, Edgar L. "Expectations and adjust-
ments in the monetary sector." Papeas and paoceedings
06 the Ameaican Economic Association 57(1967): 463-473.
Feldstein, 1971. Feldstein, Martin S. "The error forecast
in econometric models when the forecast period exo-
genous variables are stochastic." Economethica
39(1971): 55-60.
Fox, 1956. Fox, Karl A. "Econometric models of the United
States." Jouhnal 06 Political Economy 64(1956):
128-142.
Friend, 1955. Friend, Irwin, and Bronfenbrenner, Jean.
"Plant and equipment programs and their realization."
Conference, 1955, pp 53-97.
Friend, 1964. Friend, Irwin, and Jones, Robert C. "Short-
run forecasting models incorporating anticipatory
data." Conference on Research in Income and Wealth,
Models 06 Income Detehmination. Studies in Income and
Wealth, Vol 28; Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1964. pp 279-307. _
Fromm, 1964. Fromm, Gary, "Forecasting, policy simulation,
and structural analysis: some comparative results of
alternative models." American Statistical Society
Phoceedings 06 the Business and Economics Statistics
Section, 1964, pp 6-17.
Fromm, 1968. Fromm, Gary, and Taubman, Paul. Policy Simu-
lations with an economethic model. Washington:
Brookings Institution, 1968.
Gadd, 1964. Gadd, A., and Wold, H. "The Janus quotient:
a measure for the accuracy of prediction." Wold,
Herman O.A., ed., Economethic model building. Amster-
dam: North-Holland Publishing, 1964. pp 229-235.
157
Gibson, 1972. Gibson, William E. "Demand and supply
functions for money in the United States: theory and
measurement." Econometaica 40(1972): 361-370.
Gilbert, 1969. Gilbert, Roy F. "The demand for money:
an analysis of specification error." PhD dissertation,
Michigan State University, 1969.
Goldburger, 1962. Goldburger, Authur S. "Best linear
unbiased prediction in the generalized linear regres-
sion model." Jouhnal 06 the Ameaican Statistical
Association 57(.962): 369-375.
Goldfeld, 1966. Goldfeld, S. M. Commencial banh behavioa
and economic activity. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1966.
Green, 1972. Green, George in association with Liebenberg,
Maurice, and Hirsch, Albert A. "Short— and long-term
simulations with the OBE econometric model." Hickman,
1972, pp 25-123. ‘
Haitovsky, 1970. Haitovsky, Yoel, and Treyz, George. "The
analysis of econometric forecasting error." American
Statistical Association Phoceedings 06 the Business
and Economics Statistics Section 1970, pp 502-506.
Haitovsky, 1972. Haitovsky, Yoel, and Treyz, George.
"forecasts with quarterly macroeconometric models,
equation adjustments, and benchmark predictions:
the U. S. experience." Review 06 Economics and
Statistics 54(1972): 317-325.
Heller, 1965. Heller, H. R. "The demand for money: the
evidence from short-run data." Quaatehly Jouhnal 05
Economics 79(1965): 291-303.
Hendershott, 1970. Hendershott, Patric H., and deLeeuw,
Frank. "Free reserves, interest rates, and deposits:
a synthesis." Jouhnal 06 Finance 25(1970): 599-614.
Hickman, 1972. Hickman, Bert G., ed. Econometaic models
06 cyclical behavioa. New York: National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1972.
Hildreth, 1960. Hildreth, C.,and Lu, J. Y. Demand
helations with autocoaaelated distuhbances. Tech-
nical Bulletin No 276, Agricultural Experiment
Station, Michigan State University, 1960.
Hosek, 1970. Hosek, William R. "Determinants of the money
multiplier." Quahtehly Review 06 Economics and
Business 10(Summer 1970): 37-46.
158
Jorgenson, 1970. Jorgenson, Dale W.; Hunter, Jerald;
and Nadiri, M. I. "The predictive performance of
econometric models of quarterly investment behavior."
Economethica 38(1970): 213-224.
Juster, 1969. Juster, F. Thomas. "Consumer anticipations
and models of durable goods demand." Mincer, 1969,
pp 167-242.
Kalish, 1970. Kalish, Lionel III. "A study of money stock
control." Jouhnal 06 Finance 25(1970): 761-776.
Klein, 1964. Klein, Lawrence R. "A postwar quarterly
model: discription and applications." Conference
on Research in Income and Wealth, Models 06 Income
Detehmination. Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol
28; Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964.
pp 11-36. -
Klein, 1968. Klein, Lawrence R. An essay on the theoay
06 economic paediction. Helsinki: Yrj6 Jahnssonin
Saatié, 1968.
Kmenta, 1971. Kmenta, Jan. Elements 05 Econometaics.
New York: Macmillan, 1971.
Kuh, 1963. Kuh, Edwin. Capital stoch gaowth--a micho-
economethic apphoach. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1963.
Laidler, 1966. Laidler, David. "Some evidence on the
demand for money." Jouanal 06 Political Economy
74(1966): 55-68.
Liebenberg, 1966. Liebenberg, Maurice; Hirsch, Albert A.;
and Popkin, Joel. "A quarterly econometric model of
the United States: a progress report." Suavey 06
Cuaaent Business 46(May 1966): 13-39.
Liu, 1969. Liu, Ta-Chung. "A monthly recursive econo-
metric model of United States :a test of feasibility."
Review 06 Economics and Statistics 51(1969): 1-13.
Mincer, 1969. Mincer, Jacob, ed. Economic (oaecasts and
expectations. New York: National Bureau of Economic
Research, 1969.
Mincer, 1969A. Mincer, Jacob, and Zarnowitz, Victor, "The
evaluation of economic forecasts." Mincer, 1969,
pp 1-46.
Naylor, 1966. Naylor, Thomas H.: Balintfy, Joseph L.;
Burdick, Donald S.; and Kong, Chu. Computed simula-
tion techniques. New York: John Wiley, 1966.
159
Naylor, 1971. Naylor, Thomas H. Computed simulation
expeaiments with models 05 economic systems. New
York: John Wiley, 1971.
Nelson, 1972. Nelson, Charles R. The team sthuctuhe 06
intehest hates. New York: Basic Books, 1972.
Nelson, 1972A. Nelson, Charles R. "The prediction per-
formance of the FRB-MIT-PENN model of the United
States economy." Ameaican Economic Review 62(1972):
902-917.
Nelson, 1973. Nelson, Charles R. Applied time seaies
analysis. (Mimeographed). Graduate School of
Business, University of Chicago, 1973.
Pierce, 1973. Pierce, James L., and Thomson, Thomas D.
"Some issues in controlling the stock of money."
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series,
Contholling monetahy aggaegatebll: the implimen-
tation. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston,
1973, pp 115-136.
Ramsey, 1969. Ramsey, James B. “Tests for specification
errors in classical linear least-squares regression
analysis." Jouanal 06 the Royal Statistical Society
Series B, 31(1969): 350-371.
Roos, 1955. R005, Charles F. "Survey of economic fore-
casting techniques." Econometaica 23(1955): 363-395.
Silber, 1970. Silber, William L. Poatfiolio behavioa 06
6inancial institutions. New York: Holt, Rinehart,
and Winston, 1970.
Smyth, 1966. Smyth, D. J. "How well do Australian
economist's forecast?" Economic Recoad 42(1966):
293-311.
Starleaf, 1970.; Starleaf, Dennis R. "The specification
of money demand-supply models which involve the use
of distributed lags." Jouanal 06 Finance 25(1970):
743-760.
Stekler, 1970. Stekler, Herman 0. Economic floaecasting.
New York: Praeger, 1970.
Su, 1971. Su, Vincent; Haitovsky, Yoel; and Treyz, George.
"The sources of forecasting errors in an OBE econo-
metric forecast." American Statistical Association
Phoceedings 06 Business and Economic Statistics
Section 1971, pp 492-497.
160
Suits, 1962. Suits, Daniel B. "Forecasting and analysis
with an econometric model." Ameaican Economic
Review 52(1962): 104-132.
Teigen, 1964. Teigen, Ronald L. "Demand and supply
function for money in the United States: some struc-
tural estimates." Econometaica 32(1964): 476-509.
Theil, 1961. Theil, Henri. Economic fiohecasts and policy.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1961.
Theil, 1966. Theil, Henri. Applied economethic fioaecasting.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1966.
Theil, 1971. Theil, Henri. Phinciples 06 economethics.
New York: John Wiley, 1971.
Tobin, 1969. Tobin, James, and Swan, Craig. "Money and
permanent income: some empirical tests." Papeas and
picceedings 06 the Amehican Economics Association
59(1969): 285-295. -
Weintraub, 1970. Weintraub, Robert, and Hosek, William R.
"Some further reflections on and investigations of
money demand." Jouanal 06 Finance 25(1970): 109-125.
Zarembka, 1968. Zarembka, Paul. "Functional form in the
demand for money." Jouhnal 06 the Ameaican Statis-
tical Association 63(1968): 502-511.
Zarnowitz, 1967. Zarnowitz, Victor. An apphaisal 06
shoht-tehm economic (ohecasts. New York: National
Bureau of Economic Research, 1967.
Zarnowitz, 1968. Zarnowitz, Victor. "Prediction and fore-
casting, economic." Intehnational Encyclopedia 06 the
Social Sciences. New York: Macmillan & The Free
Press, 1968. Volumn 12, pp 425-439.
Zecker, 1971. Zecher, Richard. "A comment on Carl Christ's
paper." Jouanal 06 money, chedit and banking 3(1971):
461-463.
Zellner, 1958. Zellner, Arnold. "A statistical analysis
of provisional estimates of Gross National Product
and its components of selected National Income com-
ponents, and personal saving." Jouanal 05 the Amen-
ican Statistical Association 53(1958): 54-65.
CURB
CURN
CURR
DDO
DDP
DDR
NOTATION APPENDIX
Ratio of demand deposits subject to reserve re-
requirement to demand deposits held by the non-
bank public.
Ratio of demand deposits held by the non-bank
public and subject to reserve requirements to
demand deposits held by the non-bank public.
Ratio of time deposits held by the non-bank public
to time deposits of member banks.
Monetary base. Usually the base is the net source
base: the sum of unborrowed reserVes plus currency
held by the non-bank public or not included in
reserves.
Ratio of borrowed reserves to total deposits sub-
ject to the reserve requirement.
Currency and coin held by member banks and
included in reserves.
Currency in circulation.
Currency held by the public, i.e. currency com-
ponent of the money stock series.
1. The multiplier model. Ratio of currency held by
banks but not part of their reserves to currency
held by the non-bank public.
2. The Teigen model. Ratio of currency held by the
non-bank public to the money stock.
Non-Federal government and non-bank demand deposits
held at member banks subject to the reserve
requirement. ‘
Demand deposits held by the non-bank public, i.e.
the demand deposits component of the money stock
series.
Adjusted net demand deposits at all member banks.
161
DTM
M'k
RMCP
RMDD
RMDF
RMFR
RMLB
RMLG
RMTB
162
Total member bank deposits subject to the reserve
requirement.
Structural shift dummies for the Teigen model.
The ratio of Treasury deposits to demand deposits
held by the public.
Exogeneous expenditure (as used in the Teigen
model).
Ratio of private demand deposits held by non-
member banks to the money stock.
1. Multiplier models and the Brunner-Meltzer
models. Ratio of currency held by the public to
demand deposits held by the non-bank public.
2. The Teigen model. Ratio of private demand
deposits of member banks to reserves required for
those demand deposits.
Money stock held by the public, i.e. currency and
demand deposits held by the non-bank public.
Money stock component that is based on supplied
(exogeneous) reserves (as Specified in the Teigen
model).
Money multiplier.
Population of the United States including the
armed foreces overseas.
Net worth (as used in the Teigen model).
Implicit GNP price deflator.
Commercial paper rate on 4-6 month prime paper.
Implicit yield on demand deposits.
Difference between the commercial paper rate and
the Federal Reserve discount rate.
Federal Reserve discount rate.
Yield on domestic corporate bonds, Moody's Aaa
rated.
Yield on long-term government bonds.
Yield on 90-day Treasury bills.
RMTD
RRD
RRT
RSF
RSL
RSR
RSREL
RSRPD
RST
RSU
TD
TDM
YP
163
Effective yield on pass-book savings deposits at
commercial banks.
Implicit reserve requirement against demand
deposits subject to the reserve requirement.
Implicit reserve requirement against time deposits
of member banks.
Free reserves.
Total reserves plus reserves released through
changes in the reserve requirement.
Required member bank reserves.
Reserves released through changes in the reserve
requirement.
Reserves available to support private non—bank
deposits (RPD's).
Total member bank reserves.
Unborrowed reserves.
Ratio of reserves to total deposits.
Seasonal dummies.
Time deposits held by the public.
Time deposits of member banks subject to the
reserve requirement.
Ratio of time deposits held by the non-bank public
to demand deposits held by the public.
Gross National Product.
Permanent income, an exponentially weighted
average of GNP. See footnote 2, p 75.
DATA APPENDIX
The sources of data used in this study were quite stan-
dard and are listed below. Where possible seasonally ad-
justed data was used.
Reserves and member bank deposits data was taken from
Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System, revision of
"Aggregate Reserves and Member Bank Deposits," Statistical
Release H.3, April 1972. Some early data (prior to 1958)
was obtained from the Federal Reserve Bulletin.
Reserves released by changes in the reserve requirement
data series was from the Economic Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
The money stock series (i.e. demand deposits and currency
held by the non-bank public) was from the Federal Reserve
Bulletin, December 1970, pp 895-898.
Other data such as income and the interest rate series
were taken from Business Statistics, 1971. In some cases,
earlier volumes of this series were consulted.
164