5 .fi.1v II} -‘>‘ . -1 u ‘» tee-5' F "n: for “‘v' ‘ .A-T-tb" “11 w— m-.. w... . 71% -. » .{pgutll' 25“ 1.2. J - . ' 1‘, ‘ I .f , ‘ "1"”; ii 2912).“ [‘w _ m 1 ' “fl ,1??? 14%;: - 3'" V» .3. ' 4:le W . ~> , ‘r Vr' 2-K: y I quirvh' jrl”; II V .5? .l' ‘1‘ .1 L > '1’ - f1 l I“ 1 a. {It}? SSS? " «99:; «£14 ‘ a?” .1. 1“_ . “(1.33? 1._ , 1 - . . , f _ " ' . 7:114 M.) ~ 1 ' ‘ t ’5 13/33)" _ fl'i‘jfi . . » Mm ’1 A ‘ 31': fun/R in " r . /‘ ti v at.» um- ‘ .1 .' fr...) 1'! ' ’1 R 1.; J13”; ¢‘ " 5'"; ’1, ”I .3" I In A J . "I: I '1 1;."1".’;'I" ‘ \' 5' I . g— . * '1’.’ 1’1"]? 1- .' '. 1:11, NW :‘“,1 1 4 . ‘ ,1 H” R" {1‘1" 1| 1". ‘1 , . I '_ I 1' -: v "I l""'{'.l‘|"‘-l‘-;1 . 1,1 It! I' . 'I’ t" .| .. '5' g, “JIWWW. -'. I; fi'fvv’lr1‘1rr' , 4 r. ' . 1 , 1‘ -' .1" .1. “fwarenur' -‘ '1" Q .1 - . 1 - '- - / 3;“ “'14:: 3\ 5:“ I" 1 ' I1 , , .. ,' . . ".' , , (/13 .21 y/Jl'off'. ’7’ ‘I ,. ‘ . ”fl? 1 . . . "‘3" I U. 1 1111.1: “in“? gin-.11. ' 42, r ' MA" ’- w' 1 "l / . ’CY VJ.) :‘1”;'y/’ any.“ r’f' '1‘”; 7/31,’ , WW? ”6/. LIBRARY Michigan State UniversitZI-J This is to certify that the dissertation entitled AN ANALYSIS OF THE RELATIVE ECONOMICS OF SELECTED CROP SYSTEMS ACCOUNTING FOR INTERDEPENDENT CASH FLOWS ARISING FROM DIFFERENTIAL INTERTEMPORAL SOIL PRODUCTIVITY presented by Robert John Procter has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D . degree in Agricultural Economics Mom ' Major professor Date December 1, 1987 MS U i: an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 IVIESI_J RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to Lian/miss remove this checkout from ”- your record. FINES will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. AN ANALYSIS OF THE RELATIVE ECONOMICS OF SELECTED CROP SYSTEMS ACCOUNTING FOR INTERDEPENDENT CASH FLOWS ARISING FROM DIFFERENTIAL INTERTEMPORAL SOIL PRODUCTIVITY BY Robert John Procter A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1988 ABSTRACT AN ANALYSIS OF THE RELATIVE ECONOMICS OF SELECTED CROP SYSTEMS ACCOUNTING FOR INTERDEPENDENT CASH FLOWS ARISING FROM DIFFERENTIAL INTERTEMPORAL SOIL PRODUCTIVITY BY Robert John Procter This research has five inter-related components. First, a review and critique of existing investment/disinvestment models will be presented. Second, a review and critique of previously used modeling approaches is presented. Third, a reformulation of an existing investment/disinvestment model will be presented. Finially, a simulation model will be constructed which is consistent with the underlying analytical model. The review of existing investment models separates these models into independent and interdependent cash flow models. It is argued that the independent cash flow models are not really applicable to the problem being studied. One interdependent cash flow model is reviewed and critiqued. Based in part on this critique, an alternative formulation of this model is presented. The review of selected modeling approaches separates these models into two categories: Math Programming and Simulation models. Generally, the Math Programming models do a better job of describing the economics of competing production proactices at a Robert John Procter point in time. The simulation models tend to do a better Job at modeling the dynamics of the interaction between alternative rates of crop system soil loss and system cash flow. The simulation model formulated in this research makes several contributions to existing models. First, initial steps at endogenizing input use are made. Further, this model calculates relative cash flows by comparing two systems of differential erosivity, and not requiring one system to be in a steady state. Third, the model can study the asset switching problem. The model is then used to study the relative economics of agternative moldboard and chisel plow crOp systems in two areas of Michigan. In the area characterized by relatively flat terrain, and deep fertile soil, no chisel plow system could compete with the moldboard plow system. In another area of Michigan characterised by rolling terrain and varying soil depths, some chisel plow systems are competative with moldbnoard plow systems. Further, the sooner that the chisel plow system was adapted, the closer were the profit estimates of the moldboard/chisel plow combination to that of the comparable chisel plow system, when the chisel plow was used from the beginning of the analysis. Copyright by Robert John Procter 1988 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Larry Libby, J. Roy Black, A. Allan Schmid, and Lester V. Manderscheid composed my Guidance and Dissertation Committies. Larry and Roy provided the propulsion to lift this research off the ground. They all were instrumental in providing several mid - course corrections which directed the focus of the researcher to a coherent set of integrable research issues. Several professionals in the Economic Research Service and in the Soil Conservation Service of the United States Department of Agriculture provided invaluable guidance in sorting through some of the more turbid technical issues of crops, soils, and production agriculture. Most notable among this group was Dan Kugler who helped cultivate my understanding of these technical issues. My freshman english composition instructor must also be acknowledged fer he had the "vision" to asset that I would attend graduate school. Unfortunately, his lessons did not stay with me as did his vision. In passing, when one stops and thinks about what has just been completed, deciding whether or not what you did was good for you is sort of like the child who has just been administered a good V dose of cod liver oil being asked, "now wasn't that good?" Undoubtedly, one's perceptions mellow with age. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS Page LIST OF TABLES ....... . ....... . ........ . ......... . ........ .. x LIST OF PIMES ..... O ........ O O O O O OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO x1 CHAPTER ONE - FOCUS OF THE RESEARCH 1.1 Introduction ...... ..... .......................... 1 1.2 Problem Statement .......... ...... ......... ....... 1 1.3 Objectives of the Study.......................... 2 1.4 Overview of the Thesis. .......................... 3 CHAPTER TWO ’ REVIEW OF SELECTED INVESTMENT/DISINVESTMENT MODELS AND EMPIRICAL MODELS OF SOIL LOSS/ CROP SYSTEM ECONOMICS 2 1 IntrwuctionOOOOOOOOOOOO OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 5 2.2 Independent versus Interdependent asset caSh Flws O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 5 2.3 Independent Cash Flow Models .......... . ........ .. 8 2.3.1 Myopic Rule ............. ... ...... . ..... ... 8 2.3.2 Comparison of Net Present Values or Annuitie .................. ...... ....... 9 2.3.3 Perrin‘s Approach ....... .................. 11 2.3.4 Summary of Independent Cash Flow Models... 13 2.4 Interdependent Cash Flow Model - walker' 3 Method ........................... ....... 13 2.5 Summary of Investment Models ................... . 17 2.6 Review of Selected Empirical Analysis of 8011 Loss and Crop System Economics ........ .......... 18 2.6.1 Math Programming Approaches .............. 19 2.6.2 Simulation Approaches .................... 22 2.7 smry 0.0........OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.0.0.0000... 24 CHAPTER THREE - MANAGEMENT DECISION MAKING WITH INTERDEPENDENT CASH FLOWS - A REFORMULATION 3.1 Introduction .............................. . ...... 28 vii 3.2 Intertemporal Statics Approximation of a Dynamic Process ......................................... 28 3.3 Requirements of an Alternative Approach ......... . 32 3.4 Adjusting for Interdependent Cash Flows ......... 32 3.5 Mathematical Derivation of the Decision Rule .... 33 3.6 Transition Analysis when Multiple Switches are P0831b1e000.....OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO......OOOO... 36 3.7 Decision Making for the Owner versus the TenantOOOOOO.......0.0.........OOOOOOOOOOOOOO 38 3.8 Selection of the Time Horizon ...... .. ....... ..... 40 3.9 Generalizability of the Model ........... ......... 41 3.10 Summary ......................................... 41 CHAPTER FOUR - SIMULATION MODEL FORMULATION 4.1 Introduction ....... ... ........................... 43 4.2 This Models' Contribution to Studying Soil Loss and Crop System Economics ........... .. 43 4.3 Structure of the Computer Model ............ . ..... 44 4.3.1 Macro Overview of the Model..... ....... ... 45 4.3.2 Structure of Each Sub - Program..... ...... 47 4.3.2.1 Input Prompt Program .................. 47 4. 3. 2. 2 Soil Loss Calculation Program .......... 49 4. 3.2.3 Soil Productivity Program ....... . ...... 49 4. 3.2.4 Input Use Program ............. . ........ 53 4. 3. 2.5 Cash Flow Program ...................... 56 4. 3. 2. 6 Write Program .......................... 56 4.4 Summary ......................................... 58 CHAPTER FIVE - ANALYSIS OF ALTERNATIVES 5.1 Introduction .................................... 59 5.2 Alternative Scenarios ........................... 59 5.3 Saginaw Results ................................. 61 5.4 St. Joseph Results ....... . ...................... 65 5.5 Conclusions ..................................... 68 CHAPTER SIX - SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 6.1Introduction..................................... 69 6. 2 Literature Review ................. ...... . ...... 69 6. 3 mcision Making with Interdependent Cash Flows .. 69 6. 4S Simulation Model Formulation .. ................ . 7O 6. 5 Empirical Analysis ............................... 71 6. 6 Conclusions ..................................... 71 viii CHAPTER SEVEN - FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS 7.1 Introduction ..................................... 77 7.2 Model Structure Development .............. ..... ... 77 7.2.1 Incorporating Tax/Financial Structure ...... 78 7.2.2 Expand the Range of Possible Activities..... 78 7.2.3 Endogenize Equipment Selection in the Productivity Analysis .................. 80 7.2.4 Endogenize Heather ................ ........ . 80 7.3 Data Base Development ............................ 81 7.3.1 Crop Rotation. Tillage Method. Pesticide - Fertilizer Regime........ ..... .. 81 7.3.2 Crop Rotation. Tillage Method. 5011 Type. Initial Crop Yield.................... 82 7.3.3 Cost. Transition. and Selecting a Soil Conserving Strategy .................. 82 APPENDIX .................................................. 83 BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................... 92 ix 5.1 5.2 5.3 A.1 A02 A.3 A.4 A.5 LIST OF TABLES IQPLE Egg; Characteristics of Alternative Scenarios .............. 62 Cash Flow and Soil Loss - Saginaw County scenarioSOOOOOOOOO0.0000000000000000000000000.00.....0 64 Cash Flow and Soil Loss - St. Joseph County Scenarios ............................................. 67 Factor Product Prices for Inputs/Outputs Whose Price/Cost are Non-Producer Dependent ........... . ..... 85 Producer Dependent Factor Prices. ............... . ..... 87 Crop Rotations. Acreage Allocation. Initial Yields ......................... . .............. 88 Herbicide. Fertilizer. and Seed Use By Crop. Crop Rotation. and Tillage Method ..................... 90 Crop Rotation/Farm Practice. CP. Factors for Alternative Crop Rotations. Tillage Methods. and Geographic Locations .............................. 91 LIST OF FIGURES 2192!: Base 2.1 Illustration of Two Assets with Interdependent Cash Flows...................................... ...... 7 4.1 Macro Flowchart ....................................... 46 4.2 Input Prompt Program Flowchart..... ................... 48 4.3 Soil Loss Ca1cu1ation Flowchart ....................... 50 4.4 Soil Productivity - Yield Calculation Program Flowchart....................... ....... ....... 51 4.5 Input Use Program Flowchart............. ....... . ...... 54 4.6 Economic Analysis Program Flowchart ............. ...... 55 4.7 Output Program Flowchart .............................. 57 xi CHAPTER ONE FOCUS OF THE RESEARCH 1.1 Introduction Soil loss and soil productivity relationships have long been a concern to farmers, economists, scientists, and policy makers. Researchers are continuing to try to improve their understanding of the relation between soil loss today and productivity tomorrow. Agricultural economists translate this physical relation into an issue of resource management by the producer by studying the relation between producer goals, alternative management options, and the impact of differential rates of soil loss on goal attainment by the decision maker. This research will attempt to advance the thinking of analysts who pose the issue as does the agricultural economist. 1.2 Problem Statement Asset adoption/sale decision making models have generally assumed that the level of net return in a particular year to a challenger durable good is independent of how long the currently held asset is kept. Relying on this premise, backward induction solution techniques are applied to endogenously determine how long each asset should be kept. Studying adoption/sale decisions assuming cash flows are 2 interdependent is a more complex problem. Interdependent cash flows arise when, because of soil loss, today's management decisions will likely affect tomorrow's cash flows. This researcher knows of no analytic framework which can study the asset switch problem using an intertemporal statics framework which is constructed in such a way as to allow for interdependent cash flows. Moving to the empirical analysis, the reader will come to see that existing one period and multi - period models have not adequately dealt with the relation between crop systems with interdependent cash flows and asset decision making. Of critical importance is capturing the effect of a crop systems' differential rate of soil loss and net returns to the operator and/or owner. 1.3 Objectives of the Study When this research was conceived, the questions raised were concerned with furthering the understanding of the process of switching from one machinery complement to a new machinery complement, either with or without aditional changes in the farming enterprise. It was thought that how a producer went about switching machinery complements was probably an important part of the decision to switch machinery complements. After some initial investigation, a slightly different but related set of issues surfaced. One reason for the slight shift in focus was the observation that there didn't appear to be an appropriate analytic and empirical framework to apply to study 3 when producers choose to switch machinery complements. From this observation was derived the overriding objective of this research. The primary objective is to develop a workable conceptual and analytic framework for studying investment decision making when asset cash flows are interdependent. A related objective is to try to further clarify the economic roots of the transition problem. How can researchers begin to formulate the process of switching from one machinery complement to another machinery complement? Another objective is to clarify the relationships between soil loss and producer investment decisionmaking, and the impact of that relationship on the relative profitability of various courses of action. A fourth objective is to draw some inferences for erosion control policy using the information produced by this study. These inferences will be limited to the farm prodictivity dimension of selected policies. 1.“ Overview of the Thesis Chapter two presents a review of selected approaches to the (1) asset investment disinvestment (ID) problem, and (2) empirical analysis of the relation between soil loss and net returns to farm enterprises. Subsequent model deveIOpment is based, in part, on how the existing literature addresses critical aspects of the crop system selection] soil loss/ intertemporal productivity problem. Chapter three reformulates an existing decision rule used to answer the question of when one asset should be replaced by u another, when cash flows are interdependent. First, the requirements of the new approach are specified. Next, the approach is formulated for the cases of a single transition (switch between two different crop systems). Lastly, the approach is generalized to the problem of more than one transition within a given time horizon. Chapter four presents a discussion of the simulation model which is developed and applied in this research. What contributions the model makes to the study of (a) the relative economics of two or more mutually exclusive crop systems, and (b) the relative economics of combinations of mutually exclusive crOp systems, and intertemporal productivity are presented. Lastly, a more detailed discussion of each of the models' programs which comprise the model. Chapter five presents the alternative management scenarios which are analyzed with the model, the results of the analysis, and a discussion of the results. The empirical analysis is structured to (1) provide information to the research process on the relationship between the profitability of alternative management scenarios and the crop system/physical conditions assumed in each scenario, and (2) to illustrate how the model may be applied to the study of the relation between crop system profitability/ soil loss/ and intertemporal soil productivity. Chapter six presents a summary of the research and a set of conclusions. Finally, chapter seven identifies some issues for future research. CHAPTER TWO REVIEW OF SELECTED INVESTMENT/DISINVESTMENT MODELS EMPIRICAL MODELS OF SOILAEUSS/CROP SYSTEM ECONOMICS 2.1 Introduction This chapter provides the foundation for the remainder of this dissertation. Alternative approaches to the Investment/Disinvestment (ID) problem are first reviewed. Next, a review of selected empirical models used to study the relative economics of alternative agricultural practices is presented. Both independent and interdependent cash flow models are included in the review of alternative approaches to the ID problem. Prior to reviewing an interdependent cash flow model, the concept of interdependence between asset cash flows is discussed and illustrated. Both Math Programming and Simulation methods are included in the review of the selected empirical models. 2.2 Independent versus Interdependent Asset Cash Flows Analysis of the problem of capital allocation has included a focus on the problem of when to switch asset holdings. Generally referred to as the investment/disinvestment problem, the decision maker is attempting to determine the point in time when the Opportunity cost of holding the asset for one more 6 period exceeds the Opportunity cost of switching assets during this period. Most of the approaches to this problem have assumed that the level of cash flows in any subsequent year for the challenger (asset which may be required) are independent of the point in time when the assets are switched. Here, interdependent cash flows are assumed to exist when the level of annual net returns to the challenger in a given year vary as a function of when the asset trade occurs.1 That is, (2.1) dNR(t)/dt. f‘O v t=t*, . . ., r, Where, NR(t)=Net returns to the new asset in post trade year,t; T=Length of analysis. Figure 2.1 is a representation of both independent and interdependent cash flows. For purposes of illustration, assume that the two assets are two machinery complements. Tillage complement A is more erosive than the alternative complement, denoted complement B. As the soil depth declines, yield also declines. Finally, only the change in yield can affect net returns to complement B, NRb(t), between when asset B is held from t=O and when asset B is adOpted in a later time period. While these assumptions are more restrictive than what one would want to assume, they simplify the analysis and allow us to focus on the relationship between alternative transition periods and the annual returns to the new asset. As Figure 2.1 indicates, the solid line is assumed to represent the level of net returns to complement A across NR(I) Asset A adopted at t=0 ------- Asset 3 adopted at t=1 ...... Asset B adopted at t=0 Figure 2.1 Illustration of Two Assets with Interdependent Cash Flows 8 time. Initially, the net returns to complement B, indicated by the dotted line, are assumed to lie below those of complement A. Later, the exact Opposite situation arises. If one conducts the capital budgeting analysis assuming independent cash flows, ,the transition period is determined using the aformentioned curves. If, on the other hand, the analysis is conducted incorporating interdependent cash flows, one needs to consider the cash flow for complement B indicated by the dashed line. The sum of the vertical distance between the dotted and dashed curves, appropriately discounted, from some potential switch year to the end of the period, represents a component of the opportunity cost of deciding not to switch from complement A to complement B at the potential switch year.2 Reiterating, this sum of discounted differences in annual net returns, when the annual differences arise from interdependence between when asset A is traded and the annual net returns to asset B, are omitted from the analysis if the asset cash flow for the challenger is assumed to be independent. 2.3 Independent Cash Flow Models Three independent asset cash flow models will be reviewed. These are: (l) the Myopic Rule, (2) comparison of Net Present Values (NPV), and (3) Perrin's Approach.3 2.3.1 Myopic Rule Harsh, Conner, and Schwab propose an ID rule which is relatively simple and requires little information to 9 implement.” They propose that the maximum annuity of the challenger be calculated and compared to the discounted value of the next period's return for the currently held asset.5 When the maximum annuity of the challenger is at least as large as next period's discounted returns of the existing asset, it is time to switch assets. Equation (2.2) depicts this rule, (2.2) NRC/(1+r)t6 Max [("Rcu(1’/‘1*'”'AF1,1~" ([ unch(t)/(1+r)tJ'Ar ). 2,r t ...,([ NRch(t)/(l+r) ]'AFT,r)] Where, AFt’rzAnnuity factor for asset held for T years, at interest rate r; NRc(t):Net returns of currently held asset, in year t; NRch(t)=Net returns to challenger, in year t. There are three necessary conditions for this rule to result in a correct investment decision. First, only one replacement is being considered.6 Second, the level of NRch(t) V t=l,...,T is independent of the point in time when the transition occurs. Third, NRc(t) is a smooth concave function between [0,T]. 2.3.2 Comparison of Net Present Values or Annuities7 Comparing the net present values (NPV's) or annuities of the challenger(s) with that of the currently held asset marks the next step in complexity. Equation (2.3) formulates the problem for the case of NPV's. rt 1 (2.3) NPV SJCNRa(t)e' - ‘flL - - + e ”Tlgnnbum ”at - 1(1'1) + SVb(T2)e dt - Ia(0) + SVa(r1)e"T T'TZ:I 10 Where, 13(0) = Capital cost of asset A, at t = O; Ib(T1) = Capital cost of asset B, when trade occurs; NRa(t) : Net returns to asset A, in year t; NRb(t) = Net returns to asset B, in year t; SVa(T1) = Salvage value for asset A, in year T1; SVb(T2) = Salvage value for asset B, in year T2. The first step in calculating the NPV in equation (2.3) is to solve for the life of each asset, denoted T1 and T2. First, the second bracketed term, which denotes the NPV of some asset B held for T2 years, is differentiated with respect to T2. When equation (2.A) holds, the Optimal time to keep asset B has been found. -rt (2.“) 0 = d(NPVb)/dT2 = NRb(t)e -rt + (dSVb(T2)/dT2)e - rSVb(T2)e-rT2. The last term in equation (2.“) represents the opportunity cost of keeping B one more period. The entire equation is part of the opportunity cost Of keeping A one more period. Now it is possible to solve for T the Optimal life of the 1! first asset. Substituting equation (2.M) into the brackets in equation (2.3) and differentiating equation (2.3) by T1, equation (2.5) is obtained. (2.5) 0 = d mamou mea<.=<> Ami-.emca. —AT1111I- Jezezou A. m=ozquxm - z.<=u - soc mu=;<> az< e=s=. . :ax.u saga. .mao.¢c use: .aum.e cz<.m:;m.> - a =ue.=m O.eL.=Omma .58 ..<....:: A $65.5: 22.2.5: e=az. m:.b s=a=. saga. m .eu: ;.Om e=az. .0: sum .Oz sum TIP 2.....m1v “9 information which the user must provide. The user is automatically prompted for the necessary data. When the user has responded to the prompts, the data are saved in a separate program for later use. After all the data are entered, computing‘returns‘to-EASL. “.3.2.2 Soil Loss Calculation-Program This program is depicted in Figure “.3. First, to assure subsequent calculations are performed using the correct annual rate of soil loss, the rates of soil loss for each crop system are set equal to zero. Next, using the USLE, the average annual rate of soil loss is calculated For each crop system. These calculations are saved for later use. When a particular management Option contains more than-one crop system, each crop system will have a corresponding annual rate of soil loss. The form of the USLE used in the subroutine determines the average annual rate of soil loss under the specified climatic conditions, topography, andsmanagement practices. As a result, soil erosion attributable to sevens storm events is not captured. “.3.2.3 Soil Productivity Program DYNSDSP is the acronym for Dynamic Soil Depletion and Soil Productivity. As was stated earlier, this program is a modified version of the Pierce - Larson et. a1. model. Referring to Figure “.“, the reader will note that the model first calculates the weighting factors for each centimeter within a 100 cm rooting zone. These factors are used in the ategozepm assuage :o.»o_=upau mmoa ..om - m.e ou:a.m samtm: z.<=o ..xg.ezcae. mu» . ..O.vxx. g o .=>\O‘ zua. emcz=z amaze: m8. ... .8 2.2.9.5... 229.5 ne‘eaosso pzezmzcz. azuxuecz. A l \1 l ewezzz _ _ _ _ mac. ;.Om 52.9...8 1 a. 555.. 1 o . _ - .... 1E 05200 km —WO-P&O hum — _wN—J<—b—2— 11‘ 1 51 useguzepm segues; =o_um_=u.~u ape.» - xu.>..o:eoaa ..om - e.e m.=m.a m8; ...8 ..E 2...... .25... 5...... L 1111- a A 83 ....w a» .22....“ 3.2.... misc-«25 8.3 ...8 ...s... .53 us...<....5 2.4.3.38 «unmade...» 1 . v 32.3 $5.533... . .a.>:.4::... aha...“ ...-3m .2.» "93:"... “8- 3.8...» 9.2.2520 3.2.5.. 2.4.5.6 2.5.5.5. - ...ca 4. 25.....3 PP->..-n-uIU-.- 55......5 , .55... ...... ...... .... . - 93.3.3, . #3235... . 9.9.9... ...: . .25...» 32.58.... 11 ...... .... T $3.633... ...-Pubs 9.5.5.... ....n . ....n 9... £12.22. 24.8.2... $2.32... 52 calculation of the weighted productivity for a given soil depth in the root zone. After the weighting factors are determined, the sufficiency of bulk density, sufficiency of soil reaction, and the sufficiency of available water in the horizon being studied are determined. These parameters are determined by comparing selected SOILS - 5 information to various critical values contained in DYNSDSP. The product of these terms determines the unweighted productivity by horizon. Next, the weighted productivity is determined for the horizon(s) within which tillage and rooting are occurring. When soil inversion occurs, the model determines the horizon(s) contained within the 15cm plow depth, and adjusts the weighted productivity if more than one horizon is involved. Once the weighted productivity is known, the slope of the productivity curve is determined for the horizon being studied. This is, in part, dependent on the number of years it would take to deplete the horizon given the annual rate of soil loss and initial soil depth. In principle, the productivity curve is a piecewise linear function in yield - time space. As soil erosion occurs, the model shifts the 100cm rooting zone down into lower horizons. Therefore, the productivity of a given horizon at a point of time is partly a function of past soil loss. DYNSDSP has memory in two ways. First, if the current year happens to also be (1) the last year for which a particular crOp system is practiced, and (2) a new crOp system will be adopted next year, and (3) the yields for each crop in the crop sequence differed under the two crop systems, the model adjusts the 53 initial yields for each crop to reflect the soil loss which has occurred from t=0 to the beginning of the current period. If the initial yields are identical, the model simply starts with the yield at the end Of the previous period. Another way in which the model has memory is in the determination of soil loss. In any given year, the variable which indicates soil loss actually indicates the cumulative loss which has occurred. When a transition occurs between systems, the amount of soil lost up to that point in time is saved and added to the annual soil loss which occurs under the new crop system. When all the above calculations are performed for a given year, computing returns to EASL. “.3.2.“ Input Use Program Figure “.5 depicts the input use (IU) program. Within this program, the annual use, and cost, of pesticides, fertilizer, seed, potassium, and phosphate are calculated. Labor and maintenance inputs are determined in the machinery model which determines the machinery complements. These inputs whose use is dependant on a crops' yield are modeled as a constant times yield. This constant returns to size assumption may need modification. Both the quantity and total variable cost of these inputs are determined by combining (a) yield, (b) cost per unit for each input, (c) application rate for each input, and (d) percent of each acre planted to each crop. Appendix A presents and discusses how the application rates were determined. 5“ 9283...... 29.3.... mm... use... - m... 953... PmOU 32¢ mm: exam mk<..:U.— . y @345, 5.5.685 .239: .52 c.2585 5:8: 3.2.2:. mm» «.58 ...S 8553 52.5 £52.22: 95.535 mm» .x....:..... mm» .0 m fizz—Fa: 5.22 @6255 PZQZOLSU 825083 95225 .2...»— 9:55. 2.5.5.6 .8 oz . 9:352 .88 .58 2.8.... mzzaeuz c2238.: 0 92:83: A 352.2 x; $522.. 24:6..5 u...<.=52u a...§=u._ c.2533... 52.8.... “33.5 .. 5e «.53... 2 . 5.9 .apa» . . 2.3.2.. In"... :23 o: nan—=5: ..III'I'V. fix—”.9158 alllllV/g ...- m‘fla «IV. 2.3—.- . ..uhUu..uw . . b: an... . 7 MU r .2223. 39. ...:m3...- =um= nly «abusive b.- . ...- 58 evaluated. First, user provided data which are independent of any particular crop system or management option are printed. Next, crop system specific data, which are user provided, and selected endogenously calculated data are printed. At this point, the annual (1) crop yield(s), soil loss, productivity, gross revenue, total cost, and discounted net returns are printed for each year in the manager's time horizon. The last value to be printed is the NPV of the options which were analyzed. ”.4 Summary First, the contributions which this empirical model makes to the study of the on farm economics of selected methods to control soil loss were discussed. Contributions were made to the study of inter-dependent cash flow problems, comparing systems not in a steady state, endogenizing the use of selected variable inputs, the ability to study ID problems under alternative ownership structures, and including returns to land in crop system decision making. Second, a macro overview of the simulation model was presented. Part of the overview included a discussion of the relation between the structure of the simulation model and the analytic model developed in Chapter Three. Each of the individual programs was discussed in general terms and a flowchart was presented for each program, and program sequencing was discussed. CHAPTER FIVE ANALYSIS OF ALTERNATIVES 5.1 Introduction This chapter will first present the alternative scenarios which are analyzed. Part of this discussion will focus on why these scenarios were selected. Next, the results of the analysis will be presented. 5.2 Alternative Scenarios Two areas in Michigan were selected for analysis. One area is in the Southeast part of the lower peninsula, and is often referred to as the "Thumb Area." In this area, the land tends to be fairly flat, with deep, fertile, soils. Soil loss attributable to water run-off is not much of a problem in this area. The other area studied, St. Joseph's County in Southwest Michigan, contains much more rolling terrain, with varying soil depths, and a higher erosion potential. These two areas are assumed to represent a range of erosiveness and soil depths. Table 5.1 lists the characteristics of the scenarios which were studied. A scenario is comprised of (a) crop rotation; (b) machinery, denoted either by conventional (moldboard) or conservation (chisel plow); (c) tillage method, either straight up/down the field, or contouring; (d) CP factor, which is a parameter in the calculation of soil loss, and is a function of 59 60 the type of tillage equipment, crop rotation, when plowing occurs, and how much residue is left; (f) the number of components, where a component was previously defined as one crop system; (g) the planning period of the decision maker; (h) the length of time a particular component is held; and, (i) the discount rate of the decision maker. Two crop rotations were analyzed for each area. They were selected to represent rotations common in each area. As was indicated in the previous chapter, the machinery complement was developed using Muhtar's machinery complement model. His model selects a moldboard plow for the conventional complement, and a chisel plow for the conservation complement. Two tillage practices are included. Either up/down or contour plowing may be selected. The up/down plowing alternative was included to obtain some information on how a crop systems' profitability changes with a move to contour plowing. This will allow separation of profitability changes attributable to the type of plow used and the type of tilling pursued. Chemical usage for each crop rotation - machinery mix combination are presented in Appendix A. The chemical regimes were developed with the assistance of Agronomists and Entomologists at Michigan State University. The results can only be used to compare the profitability of one scenario. No significance is to be attributed to the absolute amount of profit for any one scenario. 61 5- 3 Saginaw Results Referring to Table 5.1, scenarios one through eight represent analysis conducted in the Saginaw Bay area. Table 5.2 presents net present values (NPV) for these cases. Recall that the NPV's represent the discounted net return per acre from the beginning of the analysis to infinity, and that significance can only be attributed to their relative magnitudes. As the results in Table 5.2 indicate, in all the cases evaluated, the conventional tillage system results in a greater per acre net return than all comparable conservation systems. Muhtar's study of the relative economics of conventional and conservation systems in the Saginaw area indicate that the conservation system had higher net returns than the conventional system. Two important differences between his analysis and the present analysis are (1) his model could not capture the intertemporal soil productivity relation, and (2) in his analysis the herbicide programs were assumed to remain constant. The latter point turns out to be particularly critical in the cases evaluated. Referring to cases one and two, the reader will note, referring to Table A.2, that the capital cost of the conventional system was $1.25 per acre cheaper than the corresponding conventional system. In addition, the erl, labor, and timliness costs were $5.fl5 less for the conservation system than they were for the corresponding conventional system. Comparing the herbicide program for the two systems, the per acre cost for both corn and navy beans is greater under conservation tillage than the conventional system. 62 Table 5.1 Characteristics of Alternative Scenarios Option Crop Machinery Till CP Disct. No. Yrs. Rot. Comp. Method Factor Rate Comp Held 1 C/NBJ- CVTd UP/DOWN .119 8 . 125 1 253 2 C/NB CON UP/DOWN .32 8.125 1 25 3 C/NB CVT CONTOUR .u9 8.125 1 25 u C/NB CON CONTOUR .32 8.125 1 25 5 C/NB CVT UP/DOWN .52 8.125 1 25 6 C/NB CON UP/DOWN .32 8.125 1 25 7 C/NB/SGB CVT CONTOUR .su 8.125 1 2S 8 C/NB/SGB CON CONTOUR .uu 8.125 l 25 9 C/C/SYB CVT CONTOUR .37 8.125 1 25 10 C/C/SYB CON CONTOUR .26 8.125 1 25 ll C/C/SYB CVT/CON CONTOUR .37/.26 8.125 2 10/15 12 C/C/SYB CVT/CON CONTOUR .37/.26 8.125 2 5/20 13 C/C/SYB CVT/CON CONTOUR .37/.26 8.125 2 15/10 1n C/C CVT CONTOUR .3 8.125 1 25 15 C/C CON CONTOUR .17 8.125 1 25 16 C/C CVT/CON CONTOUR .3/.l7 8.125 2 lO/lS l7 C/C CVT/CON CONTOUR .3/.17 8.125 2 15/10 Notes: l/C=Corn, NB:Navy Beans, SGB:Sugar Beets, SYB:Soybeans. 2/ CVT=Moldboard Plow, Con=Chisel Plow. appears, this indicates that the type of plow used is switched during the 25 year planning horizon. 3/This indicates the number of years each component of a management option is held for. When a slash 63 This cost differential more than overcomes the conservation systems' lower cost for fuel, labor, and timliness. It still could be the case that the conservation system would result in a greater NPV than the conventional system, but for this to occur, the intertemporal yield differentials must be great enough to overcome the per acre cost disadvantage of the conservation system. Since yields do not fall fast enough under the conventional system vis-a-vis the conservation system, the end result is a higher level of profit for the conventional system. This same analysis can be applied to a comparison of the results of options three with four, five with six, and seven with eight. These results also indicate that there is no Justification for finding the year in which a producer would shift from a conventional to a conservation system. The producer can do no better than he/she does by using the conventional system from the beginning, under the cases studied. One question which is reasonable to ask is how sensitive might the results be to a greater difference in potential erosion between systems? Comparing scenarios five with six, you can see from Table 5.1 that the CP factor, which is a function of tillage system, and cr0p rotation, and is used in the USLE calculation of soil loss, for these alternatives are .52 and .32, respectively. This is an increase in erosion differential between the conventional and conservation systems of about 50 percent, when compared to alternatives one and two. For the alternatives analyzed, this is probably the most erosive set of conditions. As Table 5.2 indicates, even here the NPV of the 6H Table 5.2 Cash Flow and Soil Loss - Saginaw Scenarios Option Soil Loss NPV (Tons/Acre/Year) (S/acre/year) 1 3.06 us7u.07 2 2.18 “386.80 3 1.53 “600.03 M 1.09 “352.69 5 3.2“ “568.18 6 1.uu uu02.18 7 3.37 7651.1u 8 2.75 7584.91 conventional system, $M568.18, is greater than the conservation system, Shu02.18. Changes in the discount rate, either higher or lower should not have any effect on the relative positions of the options which were studied. This prediction follows from the observation that the yield differential across systems across time is not significant enough to result in annual net return patterns which are different enough to allow the discount rate to affect option rank. This prediction may not hold when tax based subsidies are provided to encourage adoption of chisel plow systems. Lastly, one might ask how sensitive the results might be to the herbicide program. Here, in fact, is where one might expect that the ranks might change given different assumptions 65 about the herbicide programs. For example, the greatest difference between NPV values occurs when one compares the NPV of Options three with four, a differential of $217.3N. In this case, these systems would have the same NPV if annual conservation system costs, were $17.66/acre lower. It should be noted that the analysis assumes that transition costs are zero. If there are any costs of moving from conventional to conservation plowing, either because costs of the latter system being higher than assumed or yields are lower, the conservation system will be even less attractive. 5.4 St. Joseph's Results Turning to the results for the St. Joseph's area, one should expect to observe the effects of differential soil depletion across systems exerting more effect of options rank. Since the soils in this area are more erosive than those in the Saginaw area, a switch from a more to a less erosive crop system should exert a greater influence of system cash flows, ceteris paribus. Therefore, the relatively higher chemical costs for the conservation system should be able to be more easily counteracted by the higher productivity of the conservation system than was the case in the Saginaw area where the soil was not very erosive. Turning back to Table 5.1, scenarios 9 through 17 represent cases analyzed in the St.Joseph's area. Profit and soil loss results are presented in Table 5.3. One striking result, indicated in Table 5.3, is the 66 comparison between the NPV of the conventional system in scenario 9 ($28u3.u5), with that in scenario lO, ($3188.u2). What this result suggests is that it is at least worth conducting an analysis of when to switch systems, since the NPV Of the conservation system excedes that Of the conventional system. Looking at scenarios ll - 13, the period Of switch from the conventional to the conservation system is varied from year 5, to year 10, to year 15, respectively. The earlier that the switch occurs, the closer is the level Of NPV to that for Option 10, which corresponds with holding the conservation system from the beginning Of year one. What these results tend to suggest is that the earlier that the trade occurs, the more profitable it will be. One way to look at the results in Table 5.2 is to compare the profitability of alternative crop systems for a given type of tillage. For example, comparing the profitability of scenarios 9 with 1“, we see that a shift from a corn-corn-soybean rotation to a continuous corn rotation reduces soil erosion by 3.36 tons/acre/year, and increases profit by $11k.5u/acre, which corresponds to an annual average increase Of $9.31/acre/year. e closer together, ceteris paribus. Referring back to scenarios 9 and 10 again, one issue that the relative NPV's raises pertains to the magnitude Of any transition costs. Calculating the difference in the NPV of these twO scenarios, and analyzing this figure, one notes that 67 Table 5.3 Cash Flow and Soil Loss - St. Joseph Scenarios Option Soil Loss NPV (Tons/Acre/Year) (Slacre/year) 9 17.76 28H3.H5 10 12.u8 3188.u2 ll 17.76/12.M8 3122.32 12 17.76/12.fl8 3060.97 13 17.76/12.h8 302fl.26 1H lA.HO 2957.99 15 9.12 3107.80 16 1u.u/9.12 3192.68 17 1u.u/9.12 3171.03 break - even is attained if the NPV of scenario 10 declines by an annual average amount of $ 28.04/acre. This difference could arise in a number Of ways. Considering the fact that conservation systems require a higher level of management skill, it could be the case that the potential yields generated by the model overestimate actual yields due to a learning curve effect. Also, there may be other Opportunity costs associated with switching management practices. Comparing the NPV's for scenarios 9 and 1a, at $ 28u3.&5 and $ 2957.99, respectively, it could be argued that this is the value of using a less erosive crop rotation, keeping the tillage method and practice constant. Shifting to continuous corn from orn - corn - soybeans reduced the annual erosion by 3.36 tons/acre/year. The profit increased by _ rib-E, 68 $llu.5u/acre, or an annual average Of $9.31/acre/year.5.h 5.5 Conclusions First, given the assumptions Of this analysis, there appears to be little reason for farmers in the Thumb area to consider adopting a chisel plow system, if the decision is based solely on relative profitability. In the Options studied, no chisel plow system had a higher level Of profit than the corresponding moldboard plow system. Second, given the assumptions Of this analysis, the chisel plow system is more profitable than the corresponding moldboard plow system in the St. Joseph's area. It was also the case that the sooner the chisel plow system was adopted, the higher was the level of profit. Third, while the analysis.(a) was before taxes, and (b) assumed hat all costs and prices were constant in relative terms, the relative pattern of results should be invariant to relaxation of these assumptions, except for the introduction of subsidies for the use of chisel plow systems. Again, while the estimates of NPV were interpreted as profit estimates, they are not to be interpreted as returns to land in either the Saginaw or St. Joseph's areas. Taxes were not included, the discount rate used may be different than a potential investors weighted average cost of capital, and the NPV figure includes other returns to the current owner which would not be included in a prospective purchaser's bid price calculation. CHAPTER SIX SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 6.1 Introduction First, the literature review will be summarized. Next, the reformulation Of interdependent cash flow models will be summarized. Following this will be a review Of the simulation model. Finally, the empirical results will be summarized. 6.2 Literature Review Chapter two presents a review Of both selected disciplinary principles which address the issue Of how to decide when to trade assets and empirical studies Of the relation between soil loss and returns to the farm enterprises. It was argued that most of the analytic frameworks which address the problem of asset cash flows are independent Of one another. One model was presented which was implicitly designed to include in ID decision making an additional component Of Opportunity. 6.5 Decision Making with Interdependent Cash Flows An existing decision making model, develOped by Walker, was reformulated in order to correct for several flaws in his model. First, the one transition problem was addressed, and 69 70 then the multiple crop system switch problem was addressed. It was argued that the same framework can be used to study crop system switching from either the owner Operator or tenant's perspective. Finally, it was argued that the framework used to determine when to switch tillage complements could also be used to study other changes in a crop system which will affect the pattern Of intertemporal cash flows. 6.4 Simulation Model Formulation A modified version of a simulation model develOped by Pierce - Larson et. al. was further modified for use in this analysis. Using the parts of the model which calculate annual crop yield, a modified set of economic calculations was added tO the model. This new model (a) calculates the use Of some inputs based on yield, (b) can address the question Of when tO switch crop systems, and (c) selects a system or sequence Of systems based on the relative economics Of competing systems as Opposed to comparing the economics of a soil depleting system to one assumed to be in a steady state. It was noted that the model is written in ADVANCED BASIC, and is composed Of four sub-programs. These sub-programs calculate (1) amount Of selected variable inputs used, (2) annual soil loss, (3) annual crop yield, (4) annual cash flow, and selected discounted values. An input data and output program is also included. 71 6.5 Empirical Analysis Chapter 5 noted that two areas were selected for study. One area, Saginaw County, contained less erosive soils, and the other area, St. Joseph County, contained more rolling, erosive, soils. Two tillage systems were modeled, a moldboard and a chisel plow system. Two crop rotations for each area, representing crop rotations could in that area, were assumed in the analysis. In all cases studied for Saginaw County, the moldboard plow systems resulted in a higher net present value (NPV) than any comparable chisel plow system. Turning to St. Joseph County, there were some cases where the NPV for the chisel plow system exceeded the NPV for the comparable moldboard plow system. For these cases, the NPV Of the combination increased the earlier a switch occured. Finally, the results suggest that correct specification Of the pesticide-herbicide regime was particularly important to the relative economics Of moldboard versus chisel plow systems. 6.6 Conclusions While the empirical analysis in the previous chapter is not very exhaustive, it does convey some information about the relative profitability Of competing crOp systems under a range Of soil erosion conditions. One result Of that analysis is that even after accounting for intertemporal productivity and differences in recommended pesticide/fertilizer regimes, the change in capital costs 72 between the conventional system and conservation system must be sufficiently different in order for the crOp system using conservation tillage to be profitable in low erosion potential areas. In low erosion potential areas, the gain in discounted revenues arising from using a less erosive machinery complement is at least partially Offset by the higher variable costs associated with increased pesticide/fertilizer applications. When positive transition costs are included, the less erosive machinery complement will appear even less attractive, from a profit maximizing perspective. In low erosion areas, target subsidies may have their greatest impact on changing an investor's gO-no go decision. It is also the case that a given subsidy will likely "buy" less soil loss reduction here than in‘a more erosive area. In more erosive areas, a subsidy may be (1) a rent to the potential investor, and/or (2) an inducement to adOpt at an earlier point in time. Further, the subsidy can also be viewed as compensation for the investor's lack Of information about the economic success of a conservation tillage machinery complement. Clearly, there is ample grist here for anyone's political mill. One question for policy is whether to Offer subsidies to farmers where the economic incentive to adopt conservation tillage may not exist, or to Offer subsidies where soil loss reductions may be greater, but where farmers may already have an incentive to adopt conservation tillage. Current 73 discussions on targeting focus on allocating cost share funds to areas with the greatest soil loss. These are also the situations where farmers have the greatest incentive for voluntary adOption, ceteris paribus. This leaves three alternative justifications: to induce earlier adOption, to compensate for any perceived increased riskiness Of conservation versus conventional tillage, and to serve as a proxy for the value Of mitigating Off-site impacts. A related policy issue pertains to determining whether or not any soil savings are of sufficient value to society to compensate for any rents conferred on farmers. Analysis in Chapter Five also suggests that conservation tillage does not always pay. While soil loss is lower, and therefore, discounted gross revenues are higher, pesticide and fertilizer expenditures also tend to be higher. The question then becomes whether or not the present value of revenues minus Operating costs is greater than the sum Of (1) any increased capital cost Of the conservation system, (2) any transition costs, and (3) the farmer's risk premium associated with moving to a management system which may be perceived as being riskier. Since this research assumes away the latter two costs, which in reality are probably positive, the issue is whether or not the present value Of revenues minus Operating costs compensates for the higher capital cost of the conservation tillage system. In the cases analyzed, the answer was no in the area Of low soil erosion potential. Unless there is some paticularly unique aspects Of the 74 off-farm enviornment it would be relatively more difficult to justify subsidies as a bribe to farmers, in these areas, to reduce their rates of soil loss. Another Observation from results in Chapter Five is that when the value of increased future soil productivity attributable to lower current erosion is included in the analysis, some farmers have an incentive to act in a manner consistent with reducing off-site impacts Of soil loss. That is, there is a limit to which the farmer's interests are served by mining the soil. This limit will tend to increase with increases in net returns, to the less erosive crop system. In turn, this would tend to suggest that the allocation Of cost share funds should perhaps also be affected by income level. The analysis conducted in this research does not provide information for such a global question as: what is the correct government policy? What this research does represent is a further step towards a more complete formulation of the investment problem from the individual investors' view. In a world of voluntary adoption, this is the relevant unit Of analysis. Finally, there are some specific conclusions from the analytical model and analysis. These are presented below. First, concerning the develOpment of the analytic model, it is important to distinguish between the one trade problem and the multiple switch problem, at this level of sOphistication. With the one trade problem, a piecewise 75 linear solution algorithm can be used to solve the problem which does not require exhaustive enumeration, as does the multiple switch problem. Second, given the simplicity of the algorithm used in this model to solve the problem Of which set of crop systems to use, the analyst must pay particular attention to the set Of management Options which are selected for consideration. Taking into consideration that one management Option can be differentiated from another by (a) number Of crop systems, (b) differences in switch years, (c) types of crop rotations, and (d) types of tillage equipment, how good a selection is made depends, in part, on how good the set Of management Options is from within which one is choosing. Third, in Saginaw County, the moldboard plow systems had higher NPV's than their comparable chisel plow systems. Since the capital cost Of the moldboard and chisel plow systems were nearly identical, it was the relative yields and the pesticide-herbicide regimes which exerted the greatest effect on the relative profitability of competing systems. Fourth, for St. Joseph County, some crOp systems using the chisel plow had a higher NPV than the comparable crop system using the moldboard plow. For these cases, the joint profit of a moldboard-chisel plow combination approached the profit level of the system using the chisel plow from t=to, the sooner the chisel plow system was adOpted. Therefore, it was always better to use the chisel plow system from the beginning, rather than switching to it later. 76 Fifth, the model developed in this research, and the existing version of the Pierce et. a1. model used by ERS, are not adequate for policy analysis where accurate profit estimates for a particular system are required. This is because (a) both the model used in this research and ERS'model omit many financial and tax parameters important to a financial analysis of competing crop systems; (b) this analysis assumed that real prices would remain constant in relative terms; and (c) ERS' model calculates the maximum amount that a farmer can invest in a chisel plow system by comparing the cash flows for a moldboard plow system and a hypothetical system assumed to be in a steady state. CHAPTER SEVEN FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS 7.1 Introduction Based on the prior six chapters, what suggestions can be made regarding issues for future research? Referring back to chapter one, one goal Of this analysis was to identify a set Of issues which could comprise a research agenda in this subject matter area. For purposes of discussion, future research directions are segmented into: (1) model structure and development, and (2) data base develOpment. Further, model structure issues are limited to advancing the sOphistication of simulation approaches. 7.2 Model Structure Development Four research areas are: (l) incorporating tax/financial structure in the model, (2) expanding the range of activities a producer may pursue, (3) inbedding equipment selection in the productivity analysis, and (4) including weather in the analysis to a greater extent than is currently the case. Each of these points will be discussed below. 77 78 7.2.1 Incorporating Tax/Financial Structure This may be the most important extension which could be made to the modeling of this problem. Issues of capital availability, after tax cash flow, after tax profit, depreciation,and other financial parameters are important to the decision making process. In turn, policy analysis is improved when based on after tax profit because of the relation between after tax profit and the ability to invest. Even if the relative profitability of any two or more alternatives remain the same after tax as before tax, shifting to an after tax analysis may be important for policy analysis when policies, such as subsidy levels, are being considered. If the relative magnitudes change after tax as compared tO before tax, there is an even greater need to use an after tax analysis. 7.2.2 Expand the Range of Possible Activities At present, the various simulation models have implicitly assumed either that (a) the producer does not engage in any other activities, or (2) the producer's cash flow from other activities is separable from the investment and returns from the cropping activities being studied. At the very least, this limits the applicability Of the simulation approaches to producers who are not vertically integrated forward or backward. One possible extension would be to explicitly allow for interdependent cash flows between Operations. For example, this would allow the analyst to endogenize a livestock enterprise and study the relation between changes in the crOp 79 enterprise and the livestock enterprise. Some of the existing LP models which were reviewed in chapter two already have dealt with this issue. Another extension Of this analysis would be to allow for stochastic cash flows and to study the problem Of asset investment/disinvestment in a portfolio theory context. One contribution Of this type Of extension would be to characterize the capital allocation process Of the decision maker in a broader context. One additional extension would be to allow for a broader range of enterprises in the farm Operation. While the current analysis includes some horizontal integration, producing corn and soybeans for feed, for example, vertical forward integration into storage, transportation, and livestock activities would be some possibilities. Extending the analysis in this way may be important for several reasons. First, the issue of capital allocation in a portfolio theory context, as was discussed above, may lead to different results concerning partial allocation. Second, to the extent that alternative crop rotations are affected by livestock Operations, a shift in machinery and/or crop sequences which would be desirable from the view towards soil loss are separable cash flows, may in fact not be desirable from the expanded whole farm perspective. Third, the present model cannot be used to anaLyze the relative economics of switches in crOp rotations during the time horizon the decision maker. While the model has been 80 constructed to address this possibility, the data are not available as to how the machinery complement may change. Currently, studying switches in crOp rotations also requires that the machinery complement be traded. This arises because MACHSEL generates different machinery complements for the crop sequences studied, ceteris paribus. Information needs to be compiled on how the machinery complement may change, given a change in crop rotation. 7.2.3 Endogenize Equipment Selection in the Productivity Analysis One limit to all the simulation modeling approaches is handling the machinery complement. Selecting the appropriate mix and size Of machines is an input to the model which performs the productivity analysis. Then, the selection of a machinery complement occurs via the selection of the most profitable crop system, based in part on the productivity model. It is not necessarily the case that the type and/Or size of the machinery mix which corresponds to the Optimal crop system, as it is presently selected, is the same as would be selected based on net cash flows derived based on the productivity model. There doesn't appear to be any way to say, apriori, how the equipment sizing/selection may change. 7.2.4 Endogenize Weather Setting aside both the EPIC model and Muhtar's model, in both the ERS model and the model developed by this author, 81 weather is deterministic. Weather is accounted for only through the use of long run rainfall parameters in calculating soil loss. Including weather is important for the impact it can have on actual crop yields as this is affected by the soil type. machinery complement. and crop residue. 7.3 Data Base Development Three areas where data can be improved are: (1) the relation between crop rotation/ tillage method/ and pesticide - fertilizer regime. (2) the relation between crop rotation/ tillage method/ soil type and initial yield. and (3) the cost, process, and decision making involved in the decision to adopt some soil conserving practice. Each of these points will be discussed below. 7.3.1 Crop Rotation. Tillage Method. Pesticide - Fertilizer Regime Based on this authors' research. the pesticide - fertilizer regime assumed to be used with various crop systems can be a very important determinant of the relative economics of conventional versus conserving systems. There appears to be controversy among various researchers in this area concerning what pesticide - fertilizer regime to assume under a given set of circumstances. This should be explored not only to arrive at some consensus among researchers. but to reconcile theory with practice. 82 7.3.2 Crop Rotation. Tillage Method. Soil Type. Initial Crop Yield Again. there appears to be a lack Of consensus as to the relation among crop rotation. tillage method. soil type. and initial crop yield. It is particularly important to determine the extent to which conservation systems have higher or lower yields than a conventional system. ceteris paribus. TO the extent that more pesticides and fertilizer are used with a conservation system. relative yields. become more important. As the discount rate decreases. this Observation attains even more importance. 7.3.3 Cost. Transition. and Selecting a Soil Conserving Strategy Not much is known concerning the transition process producers go through when adopting a less erosive crop system and/or structural improvement. Referring to the machinery complement. to what extent is the Old equipment kept versus sold? What does the learning curve look like pertaining to achieving potential yields under the adopted system? APPENDIX APPENDIX DATA Economic analysis of alternative crOpping systems which attempts to endogenize intertemporal soil productivity under a given management system requires that the analyst compile data on both the relevant economic, management, and physical parameters. One possible taxonomy of the data is the following: 1. Economic - non producer dependent; 2. Economic - producer dependent: 3. Management system; and, 4. Physical system. The data used in this analysis, and the sources of the data are the subjects of this appendix. Economic - Non Producer Dependent Both the prices of selected inputs to production and outputs from production are assumed to be independent of the actions of any one producer. Table A.l lists the input and output prices assumed in this analysis. Other inputs to the production process which are producer dependent will be discussed in the following section. Economic - Producer Dependent The remaining economic parameters are (1) the discount rate; (2) annualized machinery cost; and (3) timliness, fuel, 83 84 and labor cost. The reader should note that if the analysis was extended to after tax from before tax, there would be additional producer dependent costs reflecting the producer's tax bracket, tax rates for all the relevant taxes, depreciation rates, and so forth. Table A.2 lists the values of the previously mentioned parameters. As is indicated in the table, the machinery costs used in this analysis represent the annualized cost on a per acre basis. These costs are calculated by an engineering model, MACHSEL, develOped in the Agricultural Engineering department at Michigan State University. As was discussed in chapter two, MACHSEL is a heuristic simulation model which searches for the approximately Optimal machinery complement which minimizes the annualized cost Of performing a specified set Of farming practices, for a particular crop rotation, subject to a constraint on time. When a particular complement is not able to perform the Operations within the time constraint, a penalty, in the form Of an Opportunity cost, is assessed. Adding discounted maintenance costs, discounted owner labor charges, and discounted fuel costs together, the total machine complement dependent variable cost is Obtained. Dividing discounted machinery fixed cost and machine dependent variable cost, by the appropriate annuity factor and farm size, one Obtains annualized fixed and machine dependent variable cost, on a per hectar basis. Since MACHSEL assumed a 200 hectar farm when generating the equipment complements, the value in the table assumes a farm size which is the acre c/ 85 Table A.1 Factor-Product Prices for Inputs/Outputs whose Price/Cost are Non-Producer Dependent Factor - Product33 Price ($) Amiben 8 Atrazene 2.37 Basagran 21.05 Betamix 44.07 Blazer 37.50 CrOp Oil 4.0/gal. Dual 5.96 Eptan 2.92 Lasso 5.02 Lexone 23.90 Nortron 35.50 Pyramin 13.25 Treflan 7.0 H 273 9.74 2,4 - D 2.0 NitrOgen .15 Phosporous .23 Potassium .lO Corn seedb 1.25 Navy bean seed .50 Soybean seed .28 Sugar beet seed 10.0 Cornc 2.78 bu. Navy bean 22.38 cwt. Soybeans 6.54 bu. Sugar beets 35.47 ton Notes: a/All herbicide prices are adjusted to reflect the cost per pound of active ingredient. The prices were develOped by David Tschirley and Gerald Schwab, Department Of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. August 1984. b/ Seed prices are per pound. Source:Sherril Nott, Gerald Schwab, Mike Kelsey, Jim Hilker, and Al Shapley,Estimated Crop and Livestock Budgets for 1984, Agricultural Economics Report 446, Michigan State University,February, 1984. Product prices were Obtained from: Economic Research Service, USDA, Normalized Prices,Washington, D.C., October 24. 1983. 86 equivalent Of the 200 hectar farm. Management System Data All of required data describe characteristics of the crOp system(s) which are studied. For the purposes of this discussion, the croP system is completely described when information on the following three characteristics are provided: 1. Crop rotation; 2. Tillage method (machinery complement); and, 3. Tillage practice. The machinery model used to calculate the machinery complement assumes that the farm's acreage is equally divided between the crOps in the rotation. Since the depletion/productivity model is structured on a per acre basis, for modeling purposes, each acre is assumed to be divided between the various crops in the same fraction as is the entire farm's acreage. Table A.3 lists the various crop rotations, fraction Of an acre planted to each crOp, and yields. Table A.4 lists the herbicide, pesticide, and fertilizer usage by crop rotation and machinery complement. Table A.5 lists the machinery complements and tillage practices used in the analysis. The crop rotations,machinery complements, and soil series were selected in response to the following guidelines: 1. Select crop rotations which are representative of rotations used in each study area; 2. Secect one machinery complement which uses a moldboard plow, and one which uses a chisel plow; 3. Select a soil series which is representative Of the soil characteristics found in the study area; 87 Table A.2 Producer Dependent Factor Prices Equipment Dependent Costsc Conventional Conservation ---------- Machinery Costs -- C/NBd 76.57 75.23 C/NB/SGB 96.00 92.96 0/0 77.98 72.28 C/C/SB 66.89 66.98 --------- Fuel, Labor, Timliness------- C/NB 23.34 17.79 C/NB/SGB 27.60 23.98 C/C 20.49 17.60 C/C/SB 26.22 24.95 Notes: a/ Equipment dependent costs are Obtained from a Tillage report prepared by the Department of Agricultural Economics and Agricultural Engineering, Michigan State University, Summer 1984. b/ Rate used to evaluate public projects, published by the Water Resources Council. c/ All cost are annualized cost on a $/acre basis. d/ C=Corn, NB=Navy Beans, SYB=Soybeans, SGB*Sugar Beets. C/NB denotes a corn-navy bean rotation. All other rotations can be similarly interpreted. 4. Make sure that there is compatibility between the selection made in response to the above four points; 5. Be sure that the selections above can be analyzed, which requires that there exist the necessary infor- matio on the soil, on soil erosion, on yield, and on input use for those inputs listed in Table A.4. Physical Systems Data Since the relative economics Of alternative management practices depend in part on the nature Of the underlying physical system, it is important tO be specific about what is being assumed about that system. Some Of this information is contained within the computer model and is invariant to the selection of a crop system. Other pieces 88 Table A.3 Crop Rotations, Acerage Allocation, Initial Yields Saginaw County Rotation Percent Ac. 08 NB SIB SGB (bu) (cwt) (bu) (ton) Conventional C/NB 50/50 115 13 - - C/NB/SGB 33/33/33 115 13 - 21 Conservation C/NB 50/50 115 13 - - C/NB/SGB 33/33/33 115 13 - 21 St. Joseph County Conventional 0/0 50/50 105/100b - - - C/C/SYB 33/33/33 115/105 - 38 - Conservation C/C 50/50 100/100 - - - C/C/SIB 33/33/33 115/100 - 38 - Source: Data compiled by Davidechirley in conjunction with Don Christianson. Departments Of Agricultural Economics and Crops and Soil Science, respectively. August 1984. Notes: a/C=Corn, NBeNavy Beans, SYBFSOybeans, SGBBSugar Beets b/ A/B: A - yield of corn in first year; B - yield of corn in the second year for corn. Of information are dependent on either the crop system and/or soil being studied. Two blocks Of information must be user supplied: 1. Physical system and crOp system parameters used to calculate soil loss: 2. Selected characteristics of each horizon in the soil profile of the soil series being studied. The second block of information is used in calculating the productivity index Of each horizon in the soil profile, and the 89 annual rate of soil loss. Data which are required to calculate the annual rate Of soil loss correspond to the parameters of the Universal Soil Loss Equation. These parameters are: R - Rainfall factor; CF - CrOp rotation/Farm practice composite factor; LS - Field slope/SlOpe length composite factor; TP 8 Tillage practice factor. Several of the parameters need explanation. First, the Cp factor is a function of (a) crop rotation: (b) tillage method: ! (c) when tillage occurs using a mold board plow, (d) whether : residue is removed or not, and (e) the amount Of residue 4 (lb/ac) left on the field when chisel plow is used. Table 1.5 i presents the assumptions underlying the CP factors used in the t analysis. Second, the LS factor is read Off a graph which correlates lepe length and percent slope and indicates a particular LS factor. The percent lepe which is used corresponds to the mean of the range Of possible lepe for the predominant slope range for the particular soil being used in the area being studied. Third, the TP factor is a weighting factor whose value depends on what type of plowing occurs (eg: whether straight up/down plowing is pursued, or contour plowing is used). Up/down plowing has a factor of 1.0. Data which are used to calculate soil productivity which are situation specific are Obtained from the SOILS - 5 record for the particular soil series being used. These data are: (l) depth of each horizon in the soil profile, (2) permeability Of each horizon, (3) Ph for each horizon, and (4) available water 90 Table A.4 Herbicide, Fertilizer and Seed Use by Crop, Crop Rotation, and Tillage Method Conventional Conservation Herbicides Corn, except preceding sugar beets Lasso - 2.0 Lasso - 2.5 Atrezene - .5 Atrezene - .75 Bladex - 1.0 Bladex - 1.0 Corn, preceding sugar beets Lasso - 2.0 Lasso - 2.5 Bladex - 1.5 Bladex - 1.5 Navy Beans Eptan - 2.25 Treflan - .5 Amiben - 2.0 Amiben - 2.0 Basagran - .75 Crop 011 - 1 qt./ac Soybeans Treflan - .75 Lasso - 2.5 Lexone - .38 Lexone - .38 Basagran - 1.5 Blazer - .25 Crop Oil - 1 pt./ac. Sugar Beets Pyramin - 3.0 Nortron - 2.0 Antor - 2.0 Same H 273 - .5 Betamix - 1.0 Seed application rates1 Corn 15 1b/ac Navy beans 40 1b/ac Soybeans 45 lb/ac Sugar beets 1 1b/ac Phosphatel Fertilizerl Potassiuml Corn (lb/bu) .35 1.25 .27 Navy beans (lb/cwt) .83 3.13 .83 Soybeans (lb/bu) .9 O 1.4 Sugar beets(lb/ton) 1.3 5 3.3 ‘SOurceszl/Data compiled by David Tschirley and Ted Jenne with assistance from Drs. Don Christianson and John Kells, Departments Of Agricultural Economics and Agronomy, respectively, Michigan State University, August 1984. CrOp Rotation/Farm Practice, CP, Factors 91 Table A.5 for Alternative Crop Rotations, Tillage Methods, and Geographic Locations Rotation C/NB C/NB/SGB C/NB C/NB/SGB --------------------- St. Joseph County --------------------- C/C C/C/SYB C/C C/C/SYB - -- Saginaw County - Conventional Conservation Conventional Conservation CP Factor .49/ . '52a .54 A .32 .44 .30 j .37 .17 .26 Note:a/ The first figure assumes up/down plowing and the second assumes contour plowing. capacity. Except for depth, the number used in the analysis corresponds to the mean Of the range Of possible values for each parameter for each horizon. BI BLIOGRAPHY l. 8. 9. BIBLIOGRAPHY Banks, Tim N.; Shashanka, Bhide; C. Arden Pope III; and, Earl 0. Ready. ngects Of Tenure Arrangements, Capital Constraints, and Farm Size on the Economics of Soil and Water’Conservation Practices inIIOwa.CARD Report 111, SWCP Series IV. Iowa State University. Ames, Iowa. The Center for Agriculture and Rural Development. April 1983. Burt, Oscar. "Farm Level Economics of Soil Conservation in the Palouse Area Of the Northwest." American Journal Of Agricultural Economics. ( 1) (1983) :83-89. Cummins, Ronald G. "Some Extensions Of the Economic Theory of Exhaustable Resources.” Western Economic Journal. (3)(1969). Department Of Agricultural Economics and Agricultural Engineering. Tillage Report. Department Of Agricultural Engineering. Michigan State University. Summer 1984. Farris, J. Edwin. "Analytical Techniques used in Determining the Optimal Replacement Pattern." (1)(1960):755-766. Harsh, Stephen; Conner, Larry; and Schwab, Gerald D. Managigg the Farm Business. Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Prentice- Hall. 1981. Kugler, Daniel. Variable Cost Sharing Policy Implications for KentuckyTs Jackson Purchase Area: An Economic Study Of Cash Grain Production Considering Soil Depletion. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. 1984. Mo Connell, John."An Economic Model Of Soil Conservation." Americal Journal of Agricultural Economics. (l)(1983):83-89. Muhtar, H.; Rotz, C.A. ”A MulticrOp Machinery Selection Algorithm for Differential Tillage Systems." Paper presented at the American Society Of Agricultural Engineers Meeting. University Of Wisconsin-Madison. July 27-30, 1982. 92 IO. 11. 12. 13. 93 Olsen, Kent D.; Heady, Earl 0.; Chen, Carl C.; and, Meister, Anton D. Estimated Impacts of Two Enviornmental Alternatives in Aggiculture: A Quadratic Prqgramming Analysis. CARD Report NO. 72. Iowa State University. Ames, Iowa. Center for Agriculture and Rural Development. March, 1977. Perrin, R.K. ”Asset Replacement Principles.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics.(1)l972: 60-65. Pierce, F.J.: Larson, W.E.; Dowdy, R.H.; and, Grahm, W.A.P. "Productivity of Soils Assessing Long-Term Changes Due to Erosion.” Journal of Soil and Water Conservation.(1)l983: 39-44. Pope, C. Arden III; Bhide, Shashanka; and, Ready, Earl O. The Economics Of Soil and Water Conservation Practices in Iowa: Model and Data Documentation. CARD Report 108. SWCP Series 1. Iowa State University. Ames, Iowa. Center for Agriculture and Rural Developement. August 1982. 14.Robison, Lindon J. "Investment/Disinvestment and Use Of 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. Durables: An Analytic Framework." pp. 41-56 in Models for Investment and Disinvestment Decision Making Under Uncertainity. L.J. Robison and M.H. Abkin, eds. prepared for Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. East Lansing, Mi. EPRI. Palo Alto, Ca. January, 1982. Samuelson, Paul A. ”Economics of Forestry in an Evolving Society.” Economic Inquiry. 4(1969): 466-492. Saydeger, Orhan; Vocke, Gary F.; and, Ready, Earl O. A Multi-Goal Linear Programminngnalysis Of Trade-Offs Between Production Efficiency and Soil Loss Control in U.S. Agriculture. CARD Report NO. 76. Iowa State University. Ames, Iowa. Center for Agriculture and Rural Development. January 1977. Schall, Lawrence D., and Haley, Charles C. Introduction to Financial Management. 2nd Edition. McGraw-Rill. New York. 1980. Schwab, Gerald D. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. East Lansing, MI. Personal Communication. Summer 1984. Smith, Vernon L. "Control Theory Applied to Natural and Enviornmental Resources: An Exposition.” Journal Of Enviornmental Economics and Management.4(1977 :1-2 . Tschirley, David and Jenny, Ted. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. East Lansing, MI. Personal Communication. Summer 1984. 94 21. Walker, David J. "A Damage Control Function to Evaluate Erosion Control Economics." American Journal of Economics. (4)(l982): 690-698. 22. Williams, J.R.; Dyke P.T.; and, Jones, C.R. ”EPIC-A Model for Assessing the Effects Of Erosion on Soil Productivity." Paper presented at the Third International Conference on State-Of-the-Art in Ecological Modeling. Colorado State University. May 24-28,1982. 23. United States Department Of Agriculture. Economic Research Service. Normalized Prices. Washington, D.C. October 24. P 1983. '