THE IMPLICATIONS OF RECENT ECONOMIC AND POLICY. CHANGES ON RETAIL AND FARM LEVEL DEMAND FOR FOOD COMMOOIIIEs Dissertation for the Degree Of Ph. D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY SHIRLEY ANN PRYOR 1977 1’ Ll 1?!qu K3"? .. 1.; , 3‘, .intéan Stat:~ . mecrsiqy ( ar‘fil" This is to certify that the thesis entitled The Implications of Recent Economic and Policy Changes on Retail and Farm Level Demand for Food Commodities presented by Shirley Ann Pryor has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Agricultural Economics Ph ' D ' degree in Major professor DateW 07 639 ABSTRACT THE IMPLICATIONS OF RECENT ECONOMIC AND POLICY CHANGES ON RETAIL AND FARM LEVEL DEMAND FOR FOOD COMMODITIES by Shirley Ann Pryor The major objectives of this work are to analyze some specific United States farm commodities and isolate and estimate the relevant variables affecting their consumption. The purpose is to evaluate the substitutes and complements for the particular retail products as well as the effect of income and specific marketing costs. The effect of income dependent transfer payments and food stamps on demand is also analyzed. Econometric analysis is used to determine the relationship among the variables. Unlike previous retail analysis covering many re- tail commodities, no attempt is made to account for all foods using the usual assumptions about elasticities. Instead, a system was de- veloped for-each farm commodity. Retail and farm-level data are used; the retail level data being considered especially relevant for analysis involving consumer choices. All data used is annual data published by the U. S. Department of Agriculture and the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Marketing margins are not estimated directly, rather farm-retail price differentials emerge from the estimates of the price at both the farm and retail levels. Shirley Ann Pryor In general farm-retail price differentials have declined or stayed the same over the period in question, 1952—1972, except for bread, flour packaged for retail sale and fluid milk. The percentage of the retail price going to the farmer declined in all cases. The wage of food manufacturing employees and the price of fuel has little impact on these price differentials. Food stamps and income dependent transfer payments have differ- ential effects on the various commodities and thus on the various pro- ducers, processors, retailers, and consumers of those commodities. Income-dependent transfer payments have an effect on commodities in the following order: fed-beef, non-fed beef, flour, broilers, eggs, cookies, cheese, fluid milk, ham and butter; the largest impact being on beef. Ham and butter receive a negative impact. THE IMPLICATIONS OF RECENT ECONOMIC AND POLICY CHANGES ON RETAIL AND FARM LEVEL DEMAND FOR FOOD COMMODITIES by Shirley Ann Pryor A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1977 Dedicated to my mother and father ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I wish to thank Dr. Vernon Sorenson for his encouragement and guidance throughout my academic program. I am also indebted to Dr. Glenn Johnson, Dr. Lester Manderscheid, and Dr. James Johnson for their help at various stages of my course and dissertation work. Special thanks are due to the Department of Agricultural Eco- nomics and the taxpayers of the United States for supporting me through- out my stay at Michigan State University. All the credit for any accomplishments and none of the blame for any failures goes to my friends and most of all to my mother and father. My father showed me the path. My mother widened it for me and pushed me along it. "You don't have to help me with the dishes tonight, dear, do your homework." I am still doing my homework. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES . C O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O 0 LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Chapter I. II. III. INTRODUCTION AND OBJECTIVES . . . . . . . . . . The Role of Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Objectives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Method of Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Organization of Thesis . . . . . . . . . . . FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Demand Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Framework I O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O O O The Interrelationships among Income Distribution, Income Redistribution Policies and Demand for Food . Commodity Specific Structures . . . . . . . . . . Estimation Procedure . . . . . . . . . . . STATISTICAL ANALYSIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 Outline for Presenting the Statistical Analysis . . Wheat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Modeling the Wheat Sector . . . . . . . . . . Data. Correlation Matrix, Sources of Data and Adequacy of Proxies . . . . . . . . . . . . . Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . . Milk. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Modeling the Dairy Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . Data: Correlation Matrix, Sources of Data and Adequacy of Proxies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . . Fed and Non-Fed Beef . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Modeling the Beef Sectors . . . . . . . . . . . . Data: Correlation Matrix, Sources of Data and Adequacy of Proxies . . . . . . . . . . . . . Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . . Hogs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Modeling the Hog Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . iv Page vi . viii 14 22 23 25 25 26 26 27 29 52 52 56 60 82 82 85 86 100 100 100 Chapter Page ChiCken O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O O O O O O O 112 Modeling the Broiler Sector . . . . . . . . . . . 112 Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . 121 Eggs 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 122 Modeling the Egg Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . 122 Analysis of Regression Results . . . . . . . . . 130 IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 APPENDIX A Description of Transfer Programs . . . . . . . . . . . 139 APPENDIX B Variables used in Statistical Analysis . . . . . . . . 141 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145 LIST OF TABLES Table Page 2.1 U. 8.: Transfer Programs (1950-1974) . . . . . . . . . . 16 2.2 U. S.: Benefit Outlays Under Public Income Transfer Programs, Fiscal Year 1972 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.3 U. 8.: Federal Food Stamp Program (1961-1976) . . . . . 18 3.1 The Wheat Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 3.2 Simple Correlation Matrix for Variables Used in the Wheat Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 3.3 Regression Results for Wheat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.4 Income and Food Stamps Elasticities for Wheat Products . 48 3.5 Wheat: Farm-Retail Spreads and Percent of Retail Price Going to Farmer (1950-1970) . .A. . . . . . . . . . . . 51 3.6 U. 8. Consumption of Milk and Dairy Products (1950-1970) 57 3.7 The Dairy Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 3.8 Simple Correlation Matrix for Variables Used in the Dairy Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 3.9 Regression Results for Dairy Equations . . . . . . . . . 62 3.10 Price, Income and Transfer Elasticities for Dairy Praducts O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O 0 O 65 3.11 Dairy Products: Farm-Retail Spreads and Percent of Retail Price Going to the Farmer (1950—1970) . . . . . 81 3.12 The Fed-Beef Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 3.13 The Non-Fed Beef Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 3.14 Simple Correlation Matrix for Variables Used in the Livestock and Poultry Equations . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 3.15 Regression Results for Beef . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88 3.16 Income and Transfer Elasticities for Beef . . . . . . . . 101 vi Table 3.17 3.18 3.19 3.20 3.21 3.22 3.23 3.24 4.1 Beef, Pork and Poultry: Farm Retail Spreads and Percent of Retail Price Going to Farmer (1953-1970) The Hog Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Regression Results for Hogs . Income and Transfer Elasticities for Hogs and Poultry The Broiler Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . Regression Results for Broilers . . . . . . The Egg Model . . . . . . . . . . ... . . . Regression Results for Eggs . . . . . . . . Comparison of Transfer Elasticities and Low Elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . vii Income Page 102 104 105 111 113 114 123 124 136 Figure 2.1 3.8 3.9 3.10 3.11 3.12 3.13 3.14 3.15 3.16 3.17 LIST OF FIGURES Derived Demand . U. 8.: Quantity of Wheat used for Food per Capita {1952-1972) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Farm Price of Wheat Deflated by the CPI (1952-1977) U. 8.: Quantity of Wheat Flour used in Making Bread per capita (1952-1972) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Wheat Flour used in Making Flour Packaged for Retail Sale per Capita (1952-1972) . . ' U. 8.: Quantity of Wheat Flour used in Making Cookies and Crackers per Capita (1952-1972) . . . . . . . . . U. 8.: Retail Price of Bread Deflated by the CPI (1952-1972) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. S.: Price of Flour Packaged for Retail Sale Deflated by the CPI (19.52-1972) o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 5.: Price of cookies deflated by the CPI (1952-1972). U. 8.: Bread: Price and Consumption Indexes (1952-1972) . Determination of U. S. Department of Agriculture's Farm- Retail Spreads: An Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . U. S.: Farm-Retail Price Differential for Cookies Deflated by the CPI (1952-1972) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Farm—Retail Price Differentials for Bread Deflated by the CPI (1952-1972) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. S.: Farm-Retail Price Differentials for Flour Packaged for Retail Sale Deflated by the CPI (1952-1972) . . . . . U. S.: Fluid Milk: Price and Consumption Indexes (1952-1970) e o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Cheese: Price and Consumption Indexes (1952-1970) U. S.: Butter: Price and Consumption Indexes {1952-1970) U. 8.: Quantity of Milk Produced per Capita (1952-1970). viii Page 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 49 53 54 55 66 67 68 69 Figure 3.18 3.19 3.20 3.21 3.22 3.23 3.24 3.25 3.26 3.27 3.28 3.29 3.30 3.31 3.32 3.33 3.34 3.35 3.36 3.37 U. 8.: Farm Price of Milk Deflated by the CPI (1952-1970) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Milk used for Making Fluid Milk per capita (1952-1970) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Milk used for Making Cheese per Capita (1952-1970). . . . . . . . . . . . . . U. 8.: Quantity of Milk used for Making Butter per Capita (1952"1970) o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Retail Price of Fluid Milk Deflated by the CPI (1952-1970) 0 o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 5.: Price of Cheese Deflated by the CPI (1952—1970) U. S.: Price of Butter Deflated by the CPI (1952-1970) U. 8.: Fareretail Price Differential for Fluid Milk Deflated by the CPI (1952—1970) . . . . . . . U. 8.: Beef: Price and Consumption Indexes (l953ul971). U. 8.: Price of Fed Beef Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) . U. 8.: Quantity of Fed Beef Produced per Capita (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Steak Consumed per Capita (1953-1971) . U. S.: Price of Non-Fed Beef Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Non-Fed Beef Produced per Capita (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. 8.: Quantity of Hamburger and Ground Beef Consumed per capita (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. S.: Farm-Retail Price Differentials for Beef Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 U. S.: Hogs: Price and Consumption Indexes (1953-1971). U. S.: Price of Hogs Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) U. S.: Price of Ham Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) U. 8.: Quantity of Ham and Bacon Consumed per Capita (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 0 ix Page 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 80 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 . 103 106 107 . 108 . 109 Figure 3.38 3.39 3.40 3.41 3.42 3.43 3.44 3.45 3.46 3.47 3.48 Page U. S.: Farm—Retail Price Differentials for Ham Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) c o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 110 U. S.: Broilers: Price and Consumption Indexes (1953-1971) 0 o o o I o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 116 U. S.:. Quantity of Broilers Produced per Capita (1953-1971) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 U. S.: Price of Broilers Deflated by the CPI {1953-1971) 118 U. S.: Price of Fryers Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971). . 119 U. S.: Farm—Retail Price Differentials for Broilers Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 U. S.: Eggs: Price and Consumption Indexes (1953-1971) 125 U. 8.: Quantity of Eggs Produced per Capita (1953-1971) 126 U. S.: Farm Price of Eggs Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 127 U. 8.: Retail Price of Eggs Deflated by the CPI (1953‘1971) o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 128 U. S.: Farm-Retail Price Differentials Deflated by the CPI (1953-1971) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION AND OBJECTIVES The Role of Demand An economic system is composed of an infinite number and variety of interdependent components. The problem in analyzing the system is to define possible variables in the system and postulate on their interactions. Various components of the economic system must be defined and isolated to gain an understanding of the whole. This dissertation attempts to iso- late, describe and analyze the internal domestic demand for a specific set of U. S. farm commodities. The demand for any particular product is hypothetically a func- tion of individual tastes and preferences as well as the prices of com- peting and complementary goods and income. On a national scale, variables such as age, income and geographic distribution are important as are in- flation, average income and total population. Public policies affecting these variables are also important. Programs which have a direct effect on the consumers and thus on demand are the income and in-kind transfer (i.e. food stamps) programs. There have been some large shifts in the use of some major U. S. commodities between 1951 and 1971. The quantity of wheat used for food per capita in the U. S. has declined by about 17 percent over this period. There has been a shift in use from bread to cookies and flour packaged for retail sale. The quantity of milk used has also decreased by about 22 percent. Use of fluid milk and butter declined considerably whereas the use of cheese increased. Per capita consumption of fed-beef, non-fed beef, hogs and broilers also increased, but egg usage decreased by 10 percent. Objectives Using traditional elementary demand theory and econometric analy- sis, this work attempts to isolate the variables affecting demand for some major food commodities. Particular emphasis is on food stamps and income transfer programs. Variables considered most important due to their possible implication on food demand are substitutes and complements for various food commodities, income, income distribution, and, therefore, policies to redistribute income. Only other food items are tested for their complementarity or substitutability. No attempt was made to analyze the interactions and trade offs between demand for food and demand for non- food items. The objectives of this study are to describe and analyze changes taking place in the consumption of the major food commodities.1 Within that framework are the following objectives: 1) to investigate retail product consumption; 2) to analyze the effect of income distribution and income redistribution programs on food consumption; and 3) describe and analyze the role of marketing costs and their effect on retail products. Method of Analysis A system of equations is developed for each commodity. They are assumed to be independent except where one commodity is a substitute or complement for another. 1Milk, wheat, beef, pork, broilers and eggs. Demand for farm commodities is a result of consumer perception of various retail products, not farm products. The retail product is a combination of farm commodities and marketing services. Demand for mar- keting services and farm commodities is, therefore, expressed for the retail product. Prices and quantities of major retail products are rep- resented herein in a system of equations. To analyze demand for farm commodities and retail commodities, some concept of marketing margins and costs is essential. Marketing margins are not estimated directly in this analysis but a farm-retail price differential is obtained from price analysis at the farm and retail levels. Factors proxying marketing costs are included in the farm and retail-level equations. Organization of Thesis Chapter 2 contains the analysis which underlies the work to fol- low. The first section presents the basic demand function and defines relationships between farm and retail demand. The second section in- cludes the theory and empirical evidence concerning relationships be— tween income distribution, income redistribution policies and food demand. The empirical results and analysis of the results form the major bulk of Chapter 3. (Empirical results are presented commodity by com- modity). The final pages of the chapter contain an analysis of the re- sults across the commodities for farm-retail price differentials and transfer payments. A summary is presented in Chapter 4 along with some questions raised by the analysis. CHAPTER II FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS Demand Theory The demand schedule represents the maximum commodity quantities taken by consumers at each price level in a given time period. .For a given demand schedule, everything else is assumed constant. For the in- dividual consumer demand function, income, consumer tastes and prefer— ences and consumer investments in consumer durables and disinvestment in wives as factors in home production as well as prices of food substi- tutes and complements are among the relevant variables assumed constant. In the aggregate, the above factors, as well as income distribution and demographic factors (such as total pOpulation size and age distribution) are assumed constant. A shift in any of these factors will cause a shift in the aggregate demand schedule. A shift in the demand schedule will yield a different simultaneous solution of the demand and supply functions, i.e., different values for market clearing prices and quanti- ties. Whether price and quantity are determined simultaneously is a hypothesis which can be tested. If single demand functions are used for each commodity, either own price or quantity must be assumed exogenous. If quantity is exogenous, the supply function is assumed vertical and predetermined in the time period at which we are looking at demand. If prices are exogenous, the buyer is assumed a price taker. The quantity bought has no effect on price. At the micro level for the individual 4 consumer, the function can best be expressed as quantity dependent, as the individual has little effect on price. The more aggregated, the more likely the amount bought will effect price. With agricultural products, given the relatively fixed nature of supply, once crops are planted and breeding herds established, price dependent demand equations are generally used. If supply is not assumed fixed in the given time period, para- meters can be estimated simultaneously. The elementary traditional demand equation which is far from ideal would include the commodity's own price and quantity as well as prices of other possible substitutes and complements. The number of parameters to be estimated must be less than the number of observations. Given the limited number of years for which data are available, the nume ber of variables must be severely limited. Also, the number of years of data used must be limited because the longer the time span, the more likely it is that some variables as- sumed constant have actually shifted. (Tastes and preferences are two examples). One way to deal with the problem of degrees of freedom is to divide all food into categories and use concepts suggested by economic theory to find some of the parameters, thereby reducing the number which must be directly estimated. There are costs to this procedure as well as benefits. 1 This method is used by Brandow as well as George and King. George and King's division of food into groups is less aggregated than k 1G. E. Brandow, Interrelations Among Demands for Farm Products and Implications of Market Supply, Pennsylvania Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 680, (University Park, 1961); P. S. George and G. A. King, Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United States with .fggjgctiong for 1980. Giannini Foundation Monograph No. 26 (Davis, March 1). that of Brandow because they made further assumptions about the utility of goods. However, use of these concepts requires an accounting of total income. There must be information about non-food use as well as disag- gregated food use of income. It is difficult to explain differences existing between retail and farm level demands for food. Usually, the product bought at the re- tail level is quite different from that sold at the farm level. For ex- ample, milk at the farm level becomes ice cream, cheese, yogurt, whipped cream, etc., at the retail level. Though some eggs undergo no essential transformation in form they make a transformation in place and time. Thus, there is a difference in the product whether it be form, time or place. The difference in product price at the retail and farm level re- flects supply and demand for services which change the product in time, form and place. Waldorfl attempts to measure demand for these marketing services. He believes a total consumer demand exists for marketing ser— vices, including those services which will be bought and those provided at home. Those services which will be bought, i.e. demand for marketing services, are, according to Waldorf, consumer demand for these services minus the household supply of these services. (Finding a proxy for a quantity and price of marketing services is difficult. Waldorf substitutes Bureau of Census data for "value added by manufacturers" adjusted for price changes. The quantity of marketing services consumed is the difference between value of gross output de- flated by an index of wholesale food prices and costs of materials and ¥ 1William Waldorf, "The Demand and Supply for Marketing Services," iggrnal of Farm Economics, XV, 42-60. supplies deflated by an index of materials and supplies. The price of food manufacturing services is value added in current prices divided by value added in constant prices. 4 When estimating farm level demand, the effect of marketing ser- vices on farm demand must be considered. Farm level demand without the demand for marketing services cannot be theoretically justified; it derives from the retail demand and must be analyzed as such. Demand for the retail product includes demands for marketing services and for farm products that are inputs into the retail product. Neither George and King nor Brandow attempt to handle the question of marketing services within the supply and demand framework. Instead, they link up farm and retail prices by hypothesizing about marketing firm pricing policies. Brandow, for example, assumes a constant markup plus a percentage markup.1 Thus, only retail price and commodity quan— tities will affect farm prices. George and King investigate various pricing policies and combinations of pricing policies and, as with Brandow, derive farm level demand from the estimated retail demand func- tions. 1 To obtain derived demand Friedman2 assumes inputs into the re- tail good are in fixed proportions (Figure 2.1). The demand for one of the joint inputs is derived from the difference between the supply curve for the other and the demand for the total product. Thus, the derived demand for farm goods (inputs into a retail product) is the vertical lBrandow, Interrelationships Among Demands, p. 44. 2Milton Friedman, Price Theory (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962). Price for Retail Commodity Price for Marketing Services Price for Farm Commodity Retail Commodity Supply Supply of Marketing Services P b-------- Supply of Farm Commodity Retail Demand Quantity of Retail Commodities O 1 2 3 Quantity of Marketing Services 0 1 2 3 Quantity of Farm Commodity P PR 3 -- - - - Supply of Marketing Services Retail Commodity Derived Demand for Farm Commodity Q Figure 2.1 Derived demand difference between the demand for retail products and supply of market- ing services. The maximum amount paid for a retail good is shown by the demand curve for the retail good. The minimum price for marketing services is given by the supply curve for those services. Since the retail product is produced with fixed proportions of inputs, according to the assumptions of the analysis, the demand for farm products is a residual, or the dif- ference between the two curves. Assumptions of the static model include: 1) a fixed relation- ship between farm foods and marketing services as inputs into the retail good, and 2) demands for marketing services and farm goods are not simul— taneous (except at the original equilibrium point) since each is derived from the other's supply curve.1 Richard Foote2 presents the following model of derived demand consisting of relationships for consumer demand, marketing group supply and demand, and producer's supply. Q 8 quantity consumed c Qp = quantity produced Pr = retail price P = price paid to producer D = disposable income Z 8 other factors affecting consumer demand lIbid., p. 151. 2Richard Foote, Analytical Tools for Studyingjpemand and Price Structure, U. S. Department of Agriculture Agricultural Handbook No. 146 (Washington, D. C., August 1958). 10 Z a other factors affecting marketing groups demand and supply Z i other factors affecting producer supply 1. F(Qc, P D, 21) - 0 consumer demand I, 2. g(QC, Pr’ P , 22) 0 marketing group's supply W 3- h(Qp, Pr’ PW, 22) 4. 1(Qp, Pw’ 23) 0 marketing group's demand 0 producer's supply Assuming certain equilibrium conditions, the number of equations to be estimated is limited. If Qc = Qp the marketing supply and demand equations become one. 5. j(Qc, Pr’ P , Z = 0 marketing group's behavior w 2) The system then consists of functions for marketing group's be- havior, producer supply, and consumer demand (1, 4, 5). If Q supplied by the marketing group equals the quantity demand- ed by the consumer group, retail price can be eliminated from 5 and l to give the following derived demand for the producer's product. 6. k(Qc, P = 0 w, 22, D, Z 1) Notice that 22 or factors affecting the marketing group's behavior must be included in the estimation. Foote's original four equation framework is useful. Z2 represents factors affecting both the marketing group's supply and demand. A case can be made for a differentiation of these factors affecting supply and demand. Also, the assumption that Qc - Qp will not hold except when the farm product becomes only one retail product. When there are several retail products the system of equations becomes bigger. As with previous methods, assumptions were made to eliminate variables and thus produce a derived demand. This is a "partially reduced form equation derived 11 from a structural equation by the elimination of a price through the use of equilibrium condition."1 Framework Because of the interest in livestock and food grains only, schema by Brandow and George and King of accounting for all income not appropriate for this analysis. Rather than consider each food a substitute or complement for another one, each commodity will be tinized along with its most likely substitutes. The general schema for commodity estimation is the same as of Foote except exogenous factors affecting retail supply, Z , and 2 demand, Z differ. In Foote's schema they are the same. 3 Retail demand: QR = F(PR, 21) Retail supply: QR = F(PR, PF’ 22) Farm demand: QF = F(PF, PR, 23) Farm supply: QF = F(PF, 24) QR = quantity of retail good PR = price of retail good PF - price of farm commodity QF 8 quantity of farm commodity Zl = exogenous variables affecting retail demand 22 = exogenous variables affecting retail supply Z3 = exogenous variables affecting fanm demand Z4 - exogenous variables affecting farm supply 1 Ibid., p. 102. the is item scru- that farm 12 Because of the adjustment period for some agricultural commodities, supply and demand at the farm level may not be simultaneous. The quan- tity of the commodity supplied may be determined by the price of the previous year. This hypothesis is testable. Q is then an exogenous F variable in the farm demand equations. The schema changes to: 1. Farm supply: QF = F(PF t-l’ Z4) 2. Farm demand: PF = F(QF, PR, 23) 3. Retail supply: QR = F(PR, PF’ 22) 4. Retail demand: QR = F(PR’ 21) Functions 2, 3, and 4 can be estimated simultaneously or PR can be excluded from 2 and the farm demand equation estimated independently of retail supply and demand. If the latter approach is taken, farm de- mand must be estimated as a derived demand and the effects of Z1 and 22 included in the estimation. The marketing margin or difference between price at retail and price at the farm emerges from this relationship and supply and demand for marketing services are accounted for, although not specifically test— ed for. It is not assumed that QF and QR are the same as in many in- stances, they are not. QF may become many different products at the re- tail level. Thus, the system of equations needed to explain farm level demand becomes larger as more retail products are produced from the raw product. The system for each commodity expands to several equations of type 3 and 4, two for each retail product as well as 1 and 2 (farm supply and demand). The new system becomes 1. Retail demand: R = l,...,n QR = F(PR E l3 2. Retail supply: R = l,...,n QR = F(PR, PF’ Z2) 3. Farm demand: R = l,..,n PF = F(QF, PR, Z3) 4. Farm supply: QF = F(P , E ) Ft-l 4 QF’ PF’ QR’ PR are self-explanatory equation variables. Z1 vari- ables are the substitutes and complements that retail customers would be choosing among. These would also include more general variables such as average income, population, income transfer programs, and the number of bonus food stamps or total transfers made to low income consumers. 22 variables in the retail supply equation represent inputs into retail product production. This includes changes in the farm product at the wholesale, processing and retail level. Important inputs are: labor, transportation and fuel costs, substitutable and complementary farm com— modities. Commodities labeled substitutes at the farm level are those which the processor or wholesaler considers substitutes. In processing, for example, soybean protein may be considered a partial substitute for beef, especially in longer runs; at the retail level, pork and chicken would be substitutes. Z3 variables in the farm demand equation resemble those in the retail supply equation except they must include substitutes and comple- ments for all retail production processes and the variables applicable to all, such as labor. The price or the quantity of substitutes and complements can be used. When quantities are used, it is assumed that they are predetermined in the given time period. If prices are used, it is assumed that the buyers are price takers and the prices of the various goods are not determined simultaneously. l4 Z4 variables are the inputs into the production process and other exogenous variables affecting farm supply such as policy prices. If it is hypothesized that supply is predetermined, then Z4 variables do not need to be included in the estimation. The Interrelationships Among Income Distribution Income Redistribution Policy and Demand for Food Income distribution has an affect on the demand for food; hence the implication is that income redistribution programs also affect food demand. The connections among these three variables must be established, at least partially and approximately. Transfer Payments and Income Redistribution The purpose of government transfer payments and taxation is to redistribute income to designated target groups. There are three aspects to the redistribution. One is taxation; another is deficit financing and the third is transfer. No attempt is made to take into account all as- pects of the former two processes. Much taxation and subsequent transferral of income, goods and services occurs among groups of people whose particular characteristics would be difficult to isolate. Payments are made to groups, e.g., vet- erans and the aged, based on their particular characteristics. Low income groups also obtain special consideration. Programs catering to them specifically are called income-tested programs. It is important to distinguish between programs which transfer income directly and in-kind programs which provide services or a par— ticular good instead of cash. Most relevant to this analysis are income- tested, direct income transfers and food stamp programs. 15 Tables 2.1 and 2.2 give some perspective on the particular pro— grams as related to other transfer programs and to social welfare payments in the United States. Table 2.1 lists the total social welfare programs and more specifically the public aid programs. Public aid programs in- creased from 10.6 percent of all social welfare programs in 1950 to 11.2 percent in 1970. The three income transfer payments used in this analysis are also listed. Aid to families with dependent children (AFDC) has had the largest increase in spending. A brief description of these programs ap- pears in Appendix A. Table 2.2 compares income dependent programs with other transfer programs sponsored by various government levels. Table 2.3 outlines the historical data along with the most current data on participation num- bers and total value of food stamps issued. In 1970, the program was liberalized greatly increasing the num- ber of participants and government expenditures. If April 1976 is in- dicative of the rest of 1976, federal contributions to the program for the year would amount to $5,466 million-~twice the 1974 amount and ten times the 1970 amount. Looking briefly at income distribution in the United States re- veals two major trends.1 First, the percent of aggregate income re- ceived by each fifth of the families has not changed significantly since 1947. Second, the difference between the lowest fifth and highest fifth 1Sylvia Lane, "Effectiveness of Public Income Redistributive Policies and Programs on the Redistribution of Income to Low-Income Groups" (paper presented at the meeting of the American Agricultural Economics Association, Columbus, Ohio, August 12, 1975), p. 1. 16 TABLE 2.1 U. S.: TRANSFER PROGRAMS (1950-1974)8 1950 1960 1970 1974 1974 1950 TOTAL SOCIAL WELFARE PROGRAMS Federal, state and local. Includes social insurance, public aid, health and medical programs, veterans programs, education, housing and other social welfare. (million dollars) 23,508 52,293 145,962 242,386 10.3 TOTAL PUBLIC AID PROGRAMS AFDC, 0AA, GA, Aid to permanently and totally disabled, Aid to blind, b Medical Asst. for aged (million dollars) 2,496 4,101 16,488 33,628 13.4 TOTAL PUBLIC AID AS PERCENT OF TOTAL SOCIAL WELFARE PROGRAMS 10.6% 7.8% 11.2% 13.8% SPECIFIC PUBLIC AID PROGRAMS - AFDC million dollars 556 1,055 4,857 7,991 14.3 thousand recipients 2,234 3,073 9,659 11,006 4.9 0AA million dollars 1,469 1,922 1,866 thousand recipients 2,786 2,305 2,082 GA million dollars 353 422 731 1,131 3.2 thousand recipients 413 431 547 585 1.4 aIncludes administrative costs. b Assistance; GA=General Assistance AFDC=Aid to Families with Dependent Children; OAA=Old Age Source: Abstract of the United States, 1975 (Washington, D. C.: Printing Office, 1975), p. 284. U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Statistical Government 17 TABLE 2.2 U. S.: BENEFIT OUTLAYS UNDER PUBLIC INCOME TRANSFER PROGRAMS, FISCAL YEAR 1972 (in billions of dollars) Benefit outlays, fiscal year 1972 State and Program Total Federal Local INCOME—TESTED PROGRAMS:1 Aid to families with dependent Children 6.7 3.7 3.0 Old age assistance 2.5 1.7 .8 Aid to the blind .l .06 .04 Aid to the permanently and totally disabled 1.5 8 .7 General assistance .7 .7 Veterans' pensions 2.5 2.5 National school lunch program (free or reduced-price lunches) .5 .5 Food stamps 2.0 2.0 Food distribution (to individuals and families) .3 .3 Public housing .8 .8 Medicaid 7.0 3.9 3.1 Total, income-tested programs 24.6 16.3 8.3 OTHER INCOME TRANSFER PROGRAMS: Old age and survivors insurance 34.5 34.5 Disability insurance 4.0 4.0 Railroad retirement 2.1 2.1 Civil service retirement 3.4 3.4 Other federal employee retirement 4.0 4.0 State and local retirement 3.3 3.3 Unemployment insurance 6.4 6.4 Workmen's compensation 3.0 .2 2.8 Veterans' medical care 2.2 2.2 Veterans' compensation 3.6 3.6 Medicare 8.5 8.5 Total, other programs 75.0 68.9 6.1 Total, all programs 99 6 85.2 14.4 1These programs base benefits on current needs of recipients. Source: U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1975 (Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1975) p. 281. l8 .Nom .a Amama .muammo mcauaaum unmaauo>ou ".0 .Q .aouwcaSmmzv mmma muaumaumum amuouaouauww .musuaauauw< mo .uaoa .m .D "mouaom .ooo.oomm ammo mmmam saw o.ao seem «mam osam comma asmuumaouav omma mom w.oo Noom mmmm oamm oomma .umo mmma NON n.5n maNN meow hmes mamN .umm snaa Qua m.qm amam mmma «mmm mmmm mnma mma m.qm nmna aama momm Nmam umma moa a.om mNma amaa mamm amma amma “Na q.om omm can omoa mama omma om m.nm mum «mm moo mmqa moma mm m.mm mma mum «we muoa mema mm o.mm ooa ama omm mmm Roma mm ~.~m mo moa «ma «mm coma om o.mm mm mm mm oaa mama mm o.mm mm mm mm mm aoma mm «.mm ma am om Ne moma mm e.nm ma mm mm m mama w Aa.osv Ame Ame a o asma Amumaaomv oaam> ammumu Aw .aaav Amumaaov :oaaaaav Amumaaov aoaaaaav Aooo.av mommaoauumm amuou mo unouumm amuoa mammaoauumm ou umoo osam> aawus.H amuoa mucmmauauumm mom meadow mason voamma maamum mo moam> aonmauaomav z F1 1" O :6 :9 O O O 'U :5 m 73 5 > 3 7S C O 50 U) :9 an H :9 c o n m a m C CD I" 3' o FUEL 1 PBWHR .35 1 PCKR .89 .32 1 PFLR .77 .44 .95 1 PSUGAR .71 .53 .78 .80 1 ewe .81 .11 .92 .84 .68 1 QBREAD .65 .31 .90 .96 .70 .81 1 QFLOUR -.66 .17 -.71 -.53 -.27 -.73 -.56‘ .85 1 qwroon .65 -.13 .86 .80 .56 .89 .86 -.91 -.76 1 QWHPRODLAG -.42 -.38 -.35 -.33 -.39 -.20 -.22 .01 .13 -.08 1 qwxrac -.41 .27 -.60 -.49 -.25 -.69 —.54 .86 .84 -.77 -.04 1 STAMPS -.46 -.66 -.70 -.84 -.72 -.54 -.84 .19 .22 -.52 .97 .25 1 TRANS -.61 -.65 -.82 -.92 -.79 -.65 -.9o .30 .32 -.61 .32 .30 .97 1 WAGEFME -.80 —.16 -.93 -.89 -.72 -.93 -.87 .76 .65 -.90 .28 .60 .62 .73 1 YEAR -.78 —.11 -.96 -.91 -.70 -.94 -.92 .83 .77 -.96 .21 .73 .66 .75 .95 1 r -.83 -.25 -.97 -.91 —.78 -.93 -.89 .72 .72 -.89 .25 .66 .70 .80 .95 .97 aAll quantities are per capita and all variables expressed in dollars have been deflated by the CPI (l967=100). TRANS. STAMPS and Y are deflated per capita. Further explanation and data sources for all variables can be found in Appendix B. 31 Before 1967 the decline in bread consumption could be explained by a response to price changes.1 After 1967 this was no longer possible as both prices and consumption declined (Figure 3.9). Statistical analy- sis verifies that price is not the most explanatory variable although it has an effect. The coefficient on the price of bread in Equation 1.5, Table 3.3, is very significant but the price elasticity is small. My results indicate a price elasticity of -.33. The analysis of King and George for comparison produced a price elasticity of -.15.~ Consumption of both flour purchased for retail consumption and cookies is unresponsive to price according to the statistical analysis (Equations 1.1 and 1.3). Price coefficients for both cookies and flour are insignificant. A search for possible substitutes and complements for retail products made from wheat was unsuccessful. The only sta- tistically significant substitute for wheat flour is bread and for bread the only substitute is wheat (Equations 1.1 and 1.5). The idea that there is a substitute for an item which takes such a small portion of the budget is difficult to accept. Therefore, further research is in order. What is labor in the house worth? At what in- come level, for example, would the consumer make bread instead of buy it? Equations 1.6 and 1.7 indicate that marketing costs may have an effect on consumption. The price of fuel is significant in both bread and total wheat consumption because bread is the major component of wheat used for food in the United States. Data show that fuel costs decreased relative to other goods between 1951 and 1971 and thus would have a 1U. S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Food Consumption, Prices and Expenditures, Agricultural Report No. 138 (Washington, D. C., Government Printing Office, 1968). 32 U msoaowoxo men oumuamoa moanmaum> onu um>o wumm .muouuo mumvcmum msu omoauom muamaoawmoou onu Home: mamosuomumm .Aooaumomav Hmu mnu mp mommammm soon m>mn mmanmaum> ouaum aam was wuaamo mom was moanmamm> muauamsm aa< .m xawcmma< ca mcsom on emu mumv aam mo muuaom was coaumauomom muoaaaou 4m aqo.o m HHm now mwousom mumv cam GOHuwammem umsuusm .m waawam< :H venom on cmo .muHamo “on mam vmumemo mum w mam mzms mumHHoo CH commoumxm meanum> HHm mam muHamo you mum mmHuHucmsv HH mom mee mooamwoxm onu oumoncH mmHanum> onu uo>o wumm .muouuw uumvnwum on» momoHodo muamHonmmou «no nouns mHmonucoumm .AOOOH n momHv Hmo onu up wouMHmmv soon o>m£ moHQMHum> mUHNQ HHm paw wuHamu you mum moHAMHum> huHuamsu HH< .m vaaman< :H vdsom on emu mama HHm mo muusom mam aoHumHuommv ouonaou HHw now moousom muev 0cm coHumcmHaxo uwnuusm .kumH000 vcm muHauo awn— OHQ V Hue—m mghm .mgu. .AOOHINOOHV HAD 050 N05 vOuwwav C000 N>M£ mthHOO CH vommOMQXU mwdnwwhmei HAG Ucm fiuwawu hum Ohm. wwwuwucmav HH H 00. N0. 00. mm. 0H.: n~.: 00.: 00. 00.: ms.: 00. Hm.: me. m~.: 00.: 0H. 0H.: «0.: 0~.: 00. n0.: 0H.: H0.: H0.: N0. n0.: Ho. r H 05. mm. Nu. 00.: n~.: mm.: 00. 55.: nu.: N0. 0a.: Nn. H0.: H0.: HN. NH.: «0.: 0H.: 0H. 00.: H0.: BN.: 00.: 00. 00.: N0. mzmmo<3 H 00. N0. 0~.: -.: 00.: H0. 00.: 00.: 0h. 0H.: 00. NH.: 00.: NH. 00.: 00.: H0.: 0N. Hn.: 00.: 0a.: H0.: 0N. NN.: 0o. mz<¢H H 00. NH.: 0H.: 0H.: «0. 00.: 00.: mm. -.: mm. 00.: 00.: HH. 00.: 00.: 00.: 0H. 00.: 50.: 0~.: 00.: NH. 00.: m0. mmzxHH=om oz< MUOBmm>HH 02H zH ammo wmmHn mom meH may um>o mumm mmmonucmumm uuHucmsv HH< .moHHMHHm> .muouuo unaccoum man mmoHoco muamHonmmoo mnu Haws: .A00Hns00Hv Hmo mau up wmumHmmv coon o>ms mmHHmHum> moHun HHm 0cm muHemo nun mum moHanum> .m vacmma< aH vasow on use mumv HHm mo mousom was :oHuaHuommv mumHaaoU moocowoxm mnu oumoHvaH moHanum> onu uo>o mama .muouuo vumvcwum may mmoHoao muaoHuHHmoou ecu nova: mononucmumm .H00Hum00Hv Hmu onu >0 woumHHov coon o>mn mmHanuw> ooHua HHm 0cm ouHmmo use was moHanuw> muHuemsv HH< .m vacmma< aH venom on can mumw HHm mo mousom 0am aOHumHuowov ouoHoaoo <0 Am<.v A00.0mV E a. J. as + 105 Hoe.mv Hoe.v HoN.0 mz msoamwoxm may mumoHvaH moHHMHum> mnu uo>o mumm .muouum wumvdmum mnu mmoHoeo muaoHonmooo mnu nova: mooonuaoumm .H00Hun0mHv Hmo may 00 vmumHmmc coon m>mn moHHmHum> moHun HHm 0cm muHamo use mum mmHanum> huHucmsv HH< .m vaamea< aH venom on cmo mama HHm mo mousom 0am coHumHuommv muoHaaoo <0 Hoo.Nv Hoo.nv HNo.HHV odHNNNoo om.mN : mez moocmwoxo may ouonvaH mmHanum> mnu uo>o mumm nova: mononucwumm .muouum vumstum msu omOHoam musoHonmmoo mnu .A00Hun0mHv Hmo ocu 0H wouMHmmv soon o>ms mmHHMHum> onua HHm was suHamo Hog mum moHnm :Hum> kuHuomsv HH< .m wasoaa< aH venom on :00 mumv HHm mo muusom 0am :OHumHuommv mumHaaoo HH pom ooHHm .330.H UZHHMmm NNoH:omoH mam .aH m\o Hm>mH HHnumn an saon No mUHNa NHNN mumaumm 00 vw>HmomH mom NNoH ma .eH ooH\w AnemNHus osm mummenv Hume:omN Ho mUHHe moomma H:u was» aH mumaumm 00 00>Hmowu mom NNoH ma .aH ooH\o ananHue one mammunv Nume:omN «6 uUHNe oaammee NNoHuomoH mHo .eH\o mmeoou eUHSosnn sou 66Hua HHnume meom Nan:000H 0H0 .0H\muooo Mezzo mo ooHum HHmumH Monmom ~N0HI000H 0H0 .0H N\H\0 mmmono amoHums< mo moHuu HHS?H mmmmmum NH¢HI000H 0H0 .0H\0 HHmuoH um 0mmu0 ouHca mo moHHm mmzmm NNoH:omoH mHm .0H\m ensues No uUHNe HHmuus mmegoom NNmH m< .0H\muaoo mumaumm 00 00>Hmomu muwHHoun How moHum HH000m Nan:0mmH 0H0 .0H\mucwo Ho>oH HHmuoH 0moun mana mo moHum 0<000m .soHuomamcH Hmnmvmw nova: vommoooua 0am wmumamua an Huwnuo Huom .muusn Huoa "mmmHmson was 0000a Hmumz .Hmstwu moHaoHu “mmmHmoon .0000m Hom mNoH mzH .aH ooo.H sauna .unHamus an: momUHHm .smHamue sounm o mHme m xHszmm< 141 142 uanma amulou:00mmu Noe .Hoa NNoH m< .eH ooo.ooo.H .soHuuaooee emHHosa HnHeemeaou HHono muoswoum vmumHmu Nu .N0 .00 0am oxmo .0m0u0 mosvoud ou mmHuumavcH .00 .000H :0 .uBo ooo.H vmuomHmm sH 00m: uson ummna mo muHuemav 00 00>Hmomu umocz mo moHum 030 H:u mosh cH ~.H NNmH m< .=0\0 mumsumm an 00>Hooou amass mo moHua 0Ho .m .o Noe museumm mp 000 NumH m< .nH 00H\0 00>Hmoou Amsoov moon noHIGoG you moHue ommzozm HIu you» aH museumm 00 000 man 0< .0H 00H\0 00>Hmoou AmSOov moon wwHIcos you ooHum 0Hmowu mHmmoHona HHHE HHm mo moHun zmoH HHmumu um oaHumwuma mo moHun umHnume noes new neHsa oaHmoomN 0N0 «~0H 0< .nH 00H\0 mumsumm 00 00>Hoomu mmo: How moHua 000:0 ~NOH:000H 0H0 .0H\muamo Hm>oH H230.H um umma nowuonamn How ooHun omomz A0.uaoov m NHazmmm< coauumamcw Hmumvmm Mucus .na wmmmmuoum cam wmumamum muse mmmamaon Hon mNmH ng coo.H new mummou .maoau .mxmmum mo xufiuamac M Av.uaoov m NHszmm< 144 .muumuumn< Hmowumfiumum “mumuauummscm: mo mamamo “fiA umzq omma wcwaafiwmn manmfium> wcwuu m Aw.uaouv m xHazmmm< 1'} BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Arthur, H. B. and B. W. Marion. Dynamic Factors in Vertical Commodity Systems, Research Bulletin 1065. Wooster: Ohio Agricultural Research and Development Center, 1973. Brandow, G. E. Interrelations Among Demands for Farm Products and Implica— tions of Market Supply. Pennsylvania State Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 680. University Park: 1961. Foote, Richard. Analytical Tools for Studying Demand and Price Structure. U. S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Handbook No. 146. Washington, D. C.: August 1956. Friedman, Milton. Price Theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962. George,Pu S. and King, G. A. Consumer Demand for Food Commodities in the United States with Projections for 1980. Giannini Foundation Monograph No. 26. Davis: March 1971. Hiemstra, Stephen and Egbert, Alvin. "Shifting Direct Government Payments from Agriculture to Poor People: Impacts on Food Consumption and Farm Income." Agricultural Economics Research 21 (1969), 61-69. Lane, Sylvia. "Effectiveness of Public Income Redistributive Policies and Programs on the Redistribution of Income to Low-Income Groups." Paper presented at the meeting of the American Agricultural Economics Association, Columbus, Ohio, August 12, 1975. Lee, Dae Sung and Ridgel, Gus T. Income and Food Expenditure Patterns for a Selected Group of Families in Frankfort-Franklin County. Kentucky State University. Cooperative State Research Service. Frankfort: May, 1974. Madden, Patrick J. and Yoder, Marion D. Program Evaluation: Food Stamps and Commodity Distribution in Rural Areas of Central Pennsylvania. Pennsylvania State University Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 780. University Park: June 1972. Mittelhammer, Ron and West, Donald A. "Impact of the Food Stamp Program on the Demand for Food; Some Theoretical Considerations." Paper presented at the 1974 American Agricultural Economics Association Meetings in College Station, Texas. August, 1974. Okner, Benjamin A. and Pechman, Joseph. "Who Paid the Taxes in 1966?" American Economic Review, LXIV (May, 1974), 168n174. Purcell, J. C. and Robert Raunikar. "Quantity-Income Elasticities for Foods by Level of Income." ,Journal of Farm Economics, XLIX (1967), 1410-1414. 145 146 Reynolds, M. and Smolensky, E. "Post—Fisc Distribution of Income: 1950, 1960 and 1970." Paper presented at the meetings of the Western Economic Association, June 27, 1975. Smith, James D. and Franklin, Stephen D. "The Concentration of Personal Wealth." American Economic Review, LXIV (May, 1974) 162-167. U. S. Congress. Joint Economic Committee. Public Income Transfer Pro- grams: The Incidence of Multiple Benefits and the Issues Raised by Their Receipt, by James R. Storey. Joint Committee Print, Paper No. 1. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1972. ' U. S. Department of Agriculture. AAgricultural Statistics. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1950-1975. .‘ Economic Research Service. Bonus Food Stamps and Cash Income Supplements: Their Effectiveness in EXpanding Demand for Food. Marketing Research Report No. 1034. Washington, D. C.: Govern- ment Printing Office, 1974. . Economic Research Service. Conversion Factors and Weights and Measures for Agricultural Commodities and their Products. Statistical Bulletin No. 362. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1965. . Economic Research Service. Economic Effects of the U. S. Food Stamp Program Calendar Year 1972 and Fiscal Year 1974. Agricul- tural Economic Report No. 331. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1976. . Economic Research Service. The Egg Products Industry. Mar— keting Research Report No. 917. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1971. . Economic Research Service. Farm-Retail Spreads for Food Products. Miscellaneous Publication No. 741. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1971. . Economic Research Service. Food Consumption, Prices and Ex— penditures. Agricultural Report No. 138. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1968. . Economic Research Service. Livestock and Meat Statistics. Statistical Bulletin No. 522. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1973. . Economic Research Service. Marketing and Transportation Situation Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, May, 1974. 147 . Economic Research Service. Milk Pricing, by Alden Manchester. Agricultural Economics Report No. 315. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1975. . Economic Research Service. Vertical and Horizontal Integra- tion in the Market Egg Industry, 1955-69, by George Rogers. Economic Research Service 477. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1971. United States Department of Commerce. Bureau of the Census. Census of Manufacturers. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, every five years. . Bureau of the Census. Statistical Abstracts of the United States. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1975. United States Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Esti- mated Retail Food Prices. Washington, D. C.: Government Print- ing Office, monthly. Waldorf, William. "The Demand and Supply for Marketing Services." Journal of Farm Economics, XV, 42-60. West, Donald A. and Price, David W. "The Effects of Income, Assets, Food Programs and Household Size on Food Consumption." American Journal of Agricultural Economics, LXIII (November, 1976), 725—730.