ECONOMIC CHANGE AND POLITICAL‘BEHAVIOR IN RURAL INDIA ' Dissértation for the Degree of Ph. D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY- ARUNA NAYYAR MICH-IE' '-~1975' iIBRARY a Michigan 5‘3” Universit)’ l ‘ L | &.. ‘ I " a k l I ' . "i... I ' . r ' ‘ ‘ .l ' I ’ 5 E. ‘ l ‘r I I I . . I : I" U ' " c ’ a .’ p ."l 1 “I I. ‘5! "a an. _ 1._ ....—:y”"“*" L. . = '5’ ..::~ ‘ 1 Q 5 l‘ . i I ‘- i, a. n r. --.‘ .I 5‘“- ~‘.I-- " “‘ - . ”I. . "‘1- . “VLAJ ECONOMIC CHANGE AND POLITICAL BEHAVIOR IN RURAL INDIA By Aruna Nayyar Michie AN ABSTRACT OF A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 1975 I ' ABSTRACT ECONOMIC CHANGE AND POLITICAL BEHAVIOR IN RURAL INDIA BY Aruna Nayyar Michie This study is an attempt to discover the effects of agrarian change on the political behavior of farmers, agricultural tenants and landless labor in Rajasthan state, India. Agricultural change was studied in the context of India's Intensive Agricultural Areas and High Yielding Varieties Programmes. The field work was done in two villages of Jaipur and Bharatpur districts of Rajasthan from July 1972 to June 1973. Data were processed in India from June through August 1973. The study has its origins in political development literature which emphasizes the uneven nature of economic development that results in strains on the political system. This tends to occur in "developing" countries when new institutions of government are characterized by low levels of legitimacy. It is partially a result of the dichotomization in the minds of economists and political scientists alike between growth and the social and political ramifications of change. This dichotomy in practice is reinforced by the configuration of power on the village level. In order to study the impact of agricultural change on political behavior, the methodology of political economy suggested by Norman T. Uphoff and Warren Ilchmanl was followed. The analysis is focused on the Aruna Nayyar Michie effects of change on the maximization of growth and equality (social and economic) as these goals are posited by Government of India for the nation. It was found that programs for agricultural production have increased economic and social inequality in rural areas. The dispersal of public goods and services and judicious use of patronage by local elites however, has legitimized the role of a Congress Party-dominated government as the main distributor of values in society. The adapta— tion of "traditional" economic and political forms (particularly patron- client relationships) to the modern political system serves to make landless tenants and laborers more dependent economically on landed elites. This is occurring at the same time as agrarian change, parti- cularly mechanization, makes the elite less dependent on the services of these groups. The Congress Party has won the support of the landless by promising to abolish untouchability, provide land to the tiller, and by the pro- vision of public services. All of these measure, though largely sym- bolic, have increased the villager's perceptions of the Congress Party's capacity which enables it to continue winning elections even though its programs for agricultural change increase polarization. Data were collected using a combination of survey research and participant observation. The questionnaires used are appended to the study. Finally, policy alternatives are suggested which should maximize the government's own goals of growth with equality. Their implementa- tion requires a different perception of political expediency on the part of ruling elites in India. 1Norman T. Uphoff and Warren F. Ilchman, The Political Economy of Development (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1972). ECONOMIC CHANGE AND POLITICAL BEHAVIOR IN RURAL INDIA By Aruna Nayyar Michie A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 1975 © Copyright by ARUNA NAYYAR MICHIE 1975 ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS There are many persons to whom I owe a great debt for their assistance in different capacities and stages of this study. The Department of Political Science, Michigan State University provided financial assistance for my graduate work through a teaching assistant- ship. My committee chairman, Timothy M. Hennessey, and the committee members: Frank Pinner and Robert W. Jackman helped to shape the pro— ject and offered assistance any time it was needed. I owe much to their patience and ability. Former members of the committee who either left Michigan State University or were on leave when the study was written up, also helped formulate the problem and field approach: David V. J. Bell, John Collins, Alan P. Grimes, Robert Melson, Ellen P. Mickiewicz, and Nicholaas Luykx of the Department of Agricultural Economics. Masuma Downie helped edit the final draft and Judy DeJaegher patiently typed the final copy. The field research was funded by a grant from the Midwest Universities Consortium for International Acitivities, Inc. Richard 0. Niehoff, former Liaison Officer, was especially helpful and understand- ing about the delay in conducting field work necessitated by the Indo- Pakistan war of 1971. The grant was handled by Michigan State University through the Asian Studies Center under the direction of William T. Ross. Funding for data processing was provided by a grant-in-aid from the Indian Council of Social Science Research, New Delhi, to the National iii iv Council of Applied Economic Research, Delhi. The continuing interest of Shri J. P. Naik, Member-Secretary, ICSSR was especially heartening when I would get depressed by the research findings. Members of the Statistical Laboratory at NCAER under the direction of Shri B. K. Mitra processed the data. Their warmth and interest will never be forgotten. Though I am grateful for the assistance from these institutions, full responsibility for the study is mine. The views expressed herein are my own and do not reflect those of the agencies or their personnel. Field sponsorship and affiliation were provided by the Department of Political Science, University of Rajasthan, Jaipur. I am extremely grateful to Shri S. P. Verma, former Chairman of the department for the sponsorship and to Dr. Iqbal Narain for his guidance. Shri K. C. Panda and Shri P. C. Mathur spent hours with me working on the questionnaire and approach. With their background and experience in Indian rural research, they pointed out variables which I otherwise would not have considered. Shri Nirmal Singh, Department of Sociology, University of Rajasthan also discussed the project with me and offered useful sugges- tions. The warmth and hospitality shown my husband and myself by these persons as well as Dr. C. P. Bhambhri of Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi, and Professor T. K. N. Unnithan, Head of the Department of Sociology will always be remembered. To Dr. Bhambhri we owe a special debt as he encouraged and facilitated our association with the University of Rajasthan. The University of Udaipur, Department of Extension Education was instrumental in assisting field work done in Bharatpur district. Here the assistance given by Dr. D. K. Misra, Shri M. S. Lodha, and Shri Godhara was greatly appreciated. Shri Godhara took days out of his busy schedule in Bharatpur to take us to a number of villages before we decided upon "Shivpura." Having known members of the department pre- viously, it was also a matter of personal satisfaction to renew our association. Shri Ram Singh, Home Commissioner, Government of Rajasthan expe- dited official clearance for the research. Shri V. S. Verma, Director, Census of Rajasthan not only showed us great hospitality, but gave us valuable suggestions in sample selection and methods of census taking. Electoral statistics were obtained from the Election Commission, Jaipur. Shri P. R. Mehendiratta, Director, American Institute of Indian Studies, New Delhi,and his staff, though bearing no formal responsibility for me, helped in numerous ways: by their hospitality and assistance in solving administrative matters with a minimum of tribulation. But the study is based on field work. The persons in the districts and villages where I worked are perhaps the most important. The exten- sion personnel at the panchayat samitis of "Hanumangarh" and Kumher gave freely of their time to discuss problems of extension, fertilizer, pesticides, and seed. The Patwaris in Hanumangarh and Shivpura, espec- ially the former, spent literally hours lecturing on land tenure systems and legislation in Rajasthan. They also helped make up lists of farm- ers, tenants and laborers from which the samples were drawn. The sarpanchas and other elected officials of both villages talked freely about agriculture and change and personally saw to our housing and com- fort. Obviously, were it not for the openness with which informants talked with me this study could never have been done. Though each inter- view took approximately one and a half hours, better than twice that amount of time was Spent with each family and neighbors as they offered vi a meal, milk, or simply took advantage of my presence to ask a range of questions about the United States, Delhi, or even if Neil Armstrong really landed on the moon. Were there to be a dedication of this study, it would be to the persons interviewed, and particularly to Kalu Khatik (whom the reader will meet) and his kind who will be instrumental in shaping rural politics in the years to come. Finally, a long standing intellectual debt is owed to my parents who are almost exclusively responsible for arousing my curiosity about sectors of my country that, given my urban origins, I might otherwise have had no inclination to explore. My mother's years and rural study and discussions with myself helped point directions in which I might proceed. And my debt to my husband is great. While doing his own field work and writing he not only acted as a support for mine, but also spent hours discussing and arguing points of this study with me. List of Tables. TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . INTRODUCTION. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER I. THE ISSUES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER II. THE SETTING. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER III. THE SPREAD OF AGRICULTURAL MODERNIZATION . . . . . CHAPTER IV. CHANGES IN SECURITY 0F TENURE AND EMPLOYMENT . CHAPTER V. PERCEPTIONS OF WELL-BEING. . . . . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER VI. POLITICAL MOBILIZATION: THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC BASIS. CHAPTER VII. POLITICAL OPTIONS: ACTIONS AND PERCEPTIONS. CHAPTER VIII. CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS. . . . . . . APPENDICES: APPENDIX A. FIELD METHODS AND PROBLEMS . . . . . . . . . . . . APPENDIX B. THE RESPONDENTS QUESTIONNAIRE. . . . . . . . . APPENDIX C. THE LEADERSHIP QUESTIONNAIRE . . . . . . . . . . BIBLIOGRAPHY. . . . . . . . vii . viii xi ll 36 69 104 128 148 167 198 227 233 252 255 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 3.10 3.11 3.12 3.13 4.1 4.2 LIST OF TABLES The Distribution of Candidates, Seats, and Votes in Lok Sabha Elections, 1952-67 . . The Distribution of Candidates, Seats, and Votes in State Assembly Elections, 1952-67. Hierarchy of Castes in Hanumangarh and Shivpura . Sample Breakdown by Strata. . . Adoption of Hybrid Seed by Crop and Farm Size . . . . Intention to Use Hybrid Seed in the Future by Farm Size. . . . . . . . . . . . . . Use of Chemical Fertilizers by Farm Size. . . . . Intention to Use Chemical Fertilizers in the Future by Farm Size . . . . . . . . . . . Use of Chemical Pesticides by Farm Size . . Percent of Irrigated Land by Farm Size. Utilization of Credit by Farm Size. Leaders Identified by Respondents . . . . . . . . . Whether Respondents Have Difficulty Getting Inputs On Time by Farm Size. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Who Respondents Feel Get the Inputs Readily . Availability of Credit by Size of Farm. Sources of Credit Used by Farm Size . . . . . . . . . Whether Respondents Use Extension Advice by Farm Size . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Reasons Why It is More Difficult to Lease Land. . . . Whether Agricultural Laborers Find More or Less Employment in Agriculture Now Than Previously . . viii 4O 41 57 66 71 71 73 73 75 76 78 85 86 87 88 9O 93 113 115 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 4.3 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 5.7 5.8 5.9 5.10 5.11 6.1 6.2 6.3 6.4 6.5 7.1 7.2 7.3 7.4 ix Whether Farmers Require More or Less Non-Family Labor Now . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Respondents' Evaluation of Levels of Well-Being . Respondents' Perceived Changes in Food Intake . Respondents' Perceptions of Changes in Income . Groups of People Considered to be Better Off by Respondents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Percent of Sample Strata Perceiving Specific Groups are Better Off. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Perceived Changes in Village Conditions by Sample Strata. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Perceived Reasons for Changes in Village Conditions by Sample Strata. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Respondents' Perceived Needs. . . . . . . . . . Others' Needs as Perceived by Respondents . Respondents' Perceptions of Who Can Fulfill Their Needs 0 O O C O O O O C O O O C C O O C C O O 0 Responsibility for Distribution of Inputs . Respondents' Perceptions of the Family Vote . Respondents' Perceptions of Caste Vote. . Bases on Which Respondents Feel Their Families Make Political Choices. . . . . . . . . . Bases on Which Respondents Feel Their Caste Community Makes Political Choices . . . . . Bases on Which Individual Respondents Make Political Choices . . . . . . . . . . . . Respondents' Perceptions of the Importance of Voting by Farm Size . . . . . . . . . . Reasons Why Respondents Feel Voting is Important by Farm Size. 0 O O O O O C O O O O O 0 Issues Felt to be Individually Important. Issues Considered Important by Friends. 124 129 132 133 134 136 138 139 142 143 146 147 152 152 155 156 157 168 169 171 172 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 7.5 7.6 7.7 7.8 7.9 7.10 7.11 7.12 7.13 Issues Considered Important by Villagers. Respondents' Perceptions of Why People's Welfare Is the Task of Political Leaders and Officers by Farm Size. . . . . . . . Respondents' Views of Whether Parties Can Control Government. . . . . . . . . Respondents' Perceptions About Whether Leaders Take an Interest in Their Well-Being. Why Respondents Feel Leaders Are Not Interested in Them . . . . . . . . . . Have Problems Ever Been Discussed With Leaders? . Changes Respondents Would Like to See in the Functioning of Government . How Respondents Feel Desired Changes May Be Effected. . . . . . . . . . Respondents' Voting Record. . 173 175 177 178 179 180 184 185 188 Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 3.1 LIST OF FIGURES Rajasthan State. . . . . . . . . . . Electoral-Administrative Structures in India . Output Per Hectare For Farm Size Groups. xi 43 44 98 INTRODUCTION This study has its origins in questions raised in my mind over several years. Where one's interests originate is probably less impor- tant than the shape they assume through work and study, both of which have been instrumental here. Armed with an undergraduate degree in Government, I had the unique opportunity of spending almost two years in the rural areas of Rajasthan state, India. In an administrative capacity, it was my task to "programme" young Americans into rural work to aid India's rural development. I had the chance to see how schemes are conceptualized and their implementation at the local level. The experience raised more questions than it answered. Changes in rural India have been vast since independence in 1947. The exten- sion of education and other social services into the countryside are not simply statistics: the qualitative differences are consequential. The establishment of an open political system encouraging participation and free political activity has also made a difference to people's lives. Finally, government's assumption of responsibility for its citizens' welfare including the intention to pursue economic growth .wigh social and economic equality has given the political process a unique flavor. What then raises the questions? The main issue is that the goal of economic growth -- important though it is -- has taken precedence over the longer range ones of equality and social justice. Aside from my own observations (which are admittedly limited) other observers have been struck by both the lack of change or growth in certain areas, and the increasing disparities in economic well-being between those who have always had, and those for whom sufficient food, clothing and shel- ter remain a dream. Not only journalists and scholars (Indian and for- eign) but the Government of India itself has recognized the problem. Solutions are sought, and it is partially toward this effort that this study is directed. There is a recognition that the very policies enacted to aid the 40% or so of India's citizens who live below the officially recognized level of subsistence, have often served to cut them off from sources of employment, lowering their already abysmal levels of existence. Nature too has played a cruel role. Droughts and floods occur with alarming frequency. Just as the bumper harvests of 1968-69 raised hopes of self-sufficiency in basic food grains, drought wiped out all gains. Combined with the floods of 1974, the spectre of famine once again was raised on the sub-continent. The euphoria of technical break- throughs in the hybridization of cereals, the Green Revolution, was replaced by questions such as "... will the Green Revolution turn Red?"l Since field work was undertaken for this study in 1972-73, another variable has affected growth: petroleum prices. The new varieties of 1A joke once heard about India's problems is as follows: One day as God was returning home after a full day's work, he heard someone crying. Turning to see who it was, he found it was the Egyptian President worried about the Middle East situation. God consoled him and went on his way. He soon hear another crying voice and found it was the American President concerned about Viet Nam. God consoled him also, and just as he had almost reached home,1u3heard another cry. Returning to earth he found Indira Gandhi in a pool of tears. And God cried too. Anonymous. seed require high doses of chemical fertilizers of which nitrogeneous ones are especially important. The cost of naptha and other products such as diesel has risen beyond India's capacity to pay for them. Beyond these "external" setbacks however, the basic trends of India's chosen development strategy persist: those who already have continue to gain often at the expense of those without. As resources Iggg scarce, the former persons are in a better position to acquire them. Several points should be noted in this regard. First, a commitment was made by India's nationalist movement under the umbrella of the Indian National Congress to economic growth with equality. The assumption was that overall growth would be reflected in an increased living standard for all, and that this could be attained concomitantly with the goal of equality: both economic and social. These principles are laid out in India's constitution. Each planning document and every major political party since independence has paid at least lip-service to them. These goals, however, and the means evolved for their attainment are the product of an urban and landed rural minor- ity. While one cannot presume to comment on the strength of the commit- ment to either growth or equality, one can draw attention to the follow- ing observable points. How growth wi£h_equality is to be attained has never been spelled out. The strategies for growth have emerged over a period of years since independence. These normally have emphasized production targets over their impact on social, economic or political relationships.1 In fact, equitable growth is seen as contradictory to economic development 1A8 will be shown below in Chapter I, this is not unique to India. because (given the skewed distribution of wealth already present) it involves a radical redistribution of property which is thought to be counter-productive to growth, at least in the short to medium term. Second, the particular strategy for agricultural growth developed during the food crisis of 1957-58. Given this, the emphasis is (perhaps understandably for the time) on production over social or political goals or costs. Given a scarcity of resources (primarily land and capi- tal) the most expeditious strategy is seen as one which invests these into areas (and persons) where they can be used most efficiently to give rapid production increases. This may have a certain rationale, but sub- sequent events have shown that social and political consequences cannot be separated from the strategies themselves: one cannot speak of "gen— erations of problems" to be dealt with sequentially once the basic issue of production is resolved.1 Third, this means that problems of economic growth and change are inter-disciplinary in nature though they are relegated by custom (and default) to economists alone. Almost all observers are agreed that no matter what strategies might be suggested by economists, decisions regarding their feasibility and implementation are political. Yet little has been done (until recently) by either economists or other social scientists to guide policy makers in making the choices. "Poli- tical development" studies, for example, take the point where economists leave off analysis to begin their work, taking for granted what econo- mists have said.2 One result is that post mortems of political systems 1See Welter Falcon, "The Green Revolution: Generations of Prob- lems," 1970. (Mimeographed.) 2Even the study by Robert T. Holt and John E. Turner, The Political Basis of Economic Development, (Princeton: D. Van Nostrand, 1966) though abound (which have value as will be seen below). Another is that vari- ables relevant to both fields are seen as peculiar to one or the other. Should an overlap be found, the analysis is often neither interrelated nor focused on similar issues. In the real world such dichotomies do not exist. Similar parallels can be drawn between political science and other social science disciplines. The interrelatedness of these phenomena should be obvious to the political scientist who accepts as a definition of his discipline that it is the process of the authoritative allocation of values in society. The definition of politics includes process, and therefore, change. While there is abundant change in systems of government per se, a remarkable amount of it is due to alterations in patterns of the distri- bution of values in economic and social life. This is most apparent in the "developing world" where central political authorities take respon- sibility for "modernizing" or even creating their nations, thus deliber- ately seeking to alter the allocation of values. Here lies a fertile field for the political scientist, for both explaining and predicting political change. The post mortems mentioned above represent an accumulation of research and knowledge upon which explanations and predictions can be built. Minimally, from them one can learn "what went wrong," and then devise alternate strategies for change. Combined with impact predictions and focused on policy issues, such work can present policy makers with a complete set of alternatives it accepts the notion that certain kinds of political forms are neces- sary for economic development, also accepts the economists' conception of development. And further, it can be argued that they also see cer- tain political forms arising from economic change. See Chapter 2, "A Framework for the Study of the Political Basis of Economic Growth," passim. More recent works by economists in particular who argue the primacy of politics, Gunnar Myrdal, Dudley Seers, and Michael Lipton, among others, are cited where appropriate below. from which they can choose. This approach often referred to as "poli- tical economy", serves the ends of both theory building (by explaining and predicting) and of "relevance" which operationally would seem to be addressed to policy studies.1 Both descriptive and prescriptive work is important here: the former defines parameters for policy action while the latter lays out alternatives. If the political scientist decides to direct his work toward such endeavors, he must be willing to invest time and other resources toward understanding at some minimal level the assumptions made by other disci- plines involved in the same policy area. Hence the impetus for truly inter-disciplinary work. In this study, for example, one has first to understand the economic as well as political assumptions made about growth in the agricultural sector and the possible alternative 1The political economy approach referred to here is derived from the methodology suggested by Norman T. Uphoff and Warren F. Ilchman in The Political Economy of Development (Berkeley: University of Califor- nia Press, 1972), "The New Political Economy," where they state: The focus on interaction of alternatives and valua- tions, on choices and consequences, gives a quite different slant. Though in the absence of any signi- ficant change in the existing environment there may be a .8 probability of a particular outcome, what social science should seek to establish are what actions will raise that probability if the outcome is desired, or reduce it if undesired. In the 'socio-sphere', unlike the laboratory, outcomes can be affected by modifying people's estimations of their net costs or benefits from a particular course of action. Thus, the knowledge sought is pertinent to an g§_ante calculus of economic, social, and politi- cal consequences of choice. p. 16 It is therefore important to note that it is a methodology referred to and not the full range of neo-Marxist theoretical assumptions of poli- tical economy though a nee-Marxist may emphathize with the seeming para- mountcy of economics in this study. strategies developed by economists. This does not mean the disciplines lose their distinctiveness -- only that they gain complementarity. For this study, once the decision was made to work on the political implications of a particular strategy for agrarian change, it became apparent that little material exists on the subject in political science. Considerable work has been done in other fields on the means through which change may be effected, the changes each may cause in the affected parts of the social system involved, and as regards politics, on how the "failure" of agricultural modernization may contribute to revolutionary movements. Mbst of the latter works tend to be specu- lative in that they link the "failure" of agricultural modernization with other "failures": e.g., the inability of administrative units to implement policies or more generally, the failure of modern political institutions to penetrate rural areas. That is, most of these studies are done from the "top" and do not come to grips with the local dyna— mics of rural change. Two notable exceptions to this observation must be cited. The first, Eric R. Wolf's Peasant Wars of the Twientieth Century,1 links social change arising from the transition from subsistence peasant to commercial farming with wider political change. He traces political linkages between urban and rural areas which seemingly make rural parti- cipation in revolutions possible. This is a highly suggestive piece for anyone interested in pursuing the subject. Second, Barrington Moore, Jr.'s The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, (despite arguments over the interpretations of particular 1Eric R. Wolf, Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century (New York: Harper and Row, 1969). historical events) relates types of agrarian systems and the conditions under which they change, to particular political outcomes.1 Both works attempt to come to an understanding of agrarian organization in various permutations in order to understand rural change and its impact on the wider political systems involved. It is this link that needs to be developed, as there are qualitative differences between rural and urban organization.2 Besides these, there are other works of particular utility for a variety of more specific purposes which are cited in the study and bibliography. Still, there is remarkably little appreciation in poli- tical science of the importance of agrarian systems and change for poli- tical development. Much emphasis for example, is placed on urban and state level politics without a recognition of the fact that much of what occurs at these levels has its roots in "agraria". Some of this may have to do with the origins of most current political science research which is based on the modern American experience. In the field~ of political development, it may stem from the emphasis placed on the dependent variables or indicators of "modernization": industrialization, urbanization, differentiation, etc. This emphasis tends to treat ante- cedent conditions as an undifferentiated whole.3 There is some change 1Barrington Moore, Jr., The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966). 2The distinctive aspects of rural organization are developed below in Chapter VI in relation to political mobilization. 3There are exceptions of course. See Karl W. Deutsch, "Social Mobilization and Political Development," originally published in the American Political Science Review (September l961),493-Sl4 and reprinted in Jason L. Finkle and Richard W. Gable, eds., Political Development and Social Change, second edition (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1971), pp. 384-405. Also see David E. Apter, The Politics of Modernization in outlook, but it is apparent that the importance of agrarian change is just being rediscovered.1 This study then, is the start of an attempt by one person to under- stand the relationship between agrarian and political change. The first chapter is a discussion of the assumptions held by policy makers about change and the resulting policies. The second chapter provides back- ground information about India's socio-political environment and the areas in which field work was conducted. Turning to the data, Chapter III is focused on the extent to which technical breakthroughs in grain production have been adopted by the farmers in the villages studied to see the extent to which stated assumptions about change are empirically borne out. In Chapter IV I address the effects of economic change on the socio—economic system of the villages studies; primarily the dis- placement of agricultural tenants and laborers. The effects of these changes on villagers' levels of well-being are discussed in Chapter V, and the next two chapters deal with the impact of change on the respondents' political outlook and behavior. In the concluding chapter the results of economic change are analyzed within the parameters posed by the two goals of growth and equality. Finally, suggestions are made for an alternative strategy for change which, to (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1965) in which an attempt is made to develop a typology of "traditional" societies. The Deutsch article focuses on differential responses to "modernization" which, of course presupposes differential traditional conditions. 1I use the term "rediscovered" advisedly since many studies of agrarian change and the role of government in such change used to be done in the United States -- mainly in the early part of this century. Agriculture has been rediscovered primarily through studies of "develop- ing" nations. 10 the author's mind, requires fewer political costs in the longer run without sacrificing increased production which is obviously and urgently needed. CHAPTER I THE ISSUES As stated, this study was undertaken to discover the effect of agricultural change if any, on the political attitudes and behavior of farmers, agricultural tenants, and landless labor in Rajasthan, India. Agricultural change was studied in the context of India's Intensive Agricultural Areas and High Yielding Varities Programmes since it is under these schemes that the greater part of governmental inputs and efforts are channeled to increase production and raise the levels of well-being in the rural sector. The study has its origins in premises drawn from the body of thought on political and economic development. There are areas of over- lap between the two: politics determines the kind and pace of economic change, while economic change affects the political system through new demands and conflicts created by differential impact. Central to the process is the distribution of benefits from economic growth, the demands placed for these on the political system, and dislocations in employment and status caused by the process. In the language of poli- tical economy, there are certain goals posited for the Indian political system. Foremost among these are those of social and economic quality and better living standards for all citizens.1 The means used to attain 1See the Preamble, The Constitution of India (Delhi: The Govern- ment Press, 1967). ll 12 any goal may have differing impacts on diverse groups. The purpose of this study is to discover what these have been for one set of policies and the costs they have entailed for the political system. An outline is provided for an alternative approach suggesting means which might require fewer political costs in the long run. The bulk of writings on political and economic development stress their inter-relationship.1 It is one of the accepted notions of poli- tical development that economic change may intensify existing conflict. New cleavages are created through the redistribution of goods and ser- vices. Research has been conducted on differential economic impacts and some on the effects of these on system maintenance or revolution. Overall, however, little analysis has been done to analyze the poli— tical effects of economic change until conflict reaches revolutionary proportions. Scholars who emphasize system maintenance stress that variable above the quality of stability required for it. Between total quiescense and revolution lies a wide range of possible action and reaction and it is this spectrum that is of interest here. The primary theme then is that of conflict as a product of econo- mic change. The assumption is that people regardless of cultural pre- conditioning respond either positively or negatively to changes affect- ing their lives. Their reaction will focus on the authority felt to be responsible for those changes. In this sense, politics reflects 1Among many others, see Irving Horowitz, Three Worlds of Develop: ment (New York: Oxford University Press, 1966); Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968); and Gunnar Myrdal, Asian Drama (New York: The Twentieth Century Fund, 1968) and The Challenge of World Poverty (New York: Vin- tage Books, 1970). Horowitz stresses the revolutionary potential of change which he sees as perhaps the only certain way in which social justice can be attained. Huntington, on the other hand, feels the maintenance of a competitive system is the answer. 13 economics. The decision to induce change (and its kind and degree) is political, but here politics reflects rather than initiates. Tied to this is another assumption. Economic change increases poli- tical mobilization. Groups positively affected by economic programs may see it in their interest to support actively the authority felt to be responsible for their benefits: an effort might be made either to in- crease or at least to maintain their present level. Those perceiving themselves to be deprived may participate to press for changes in policy. Participation may occur within established processes, or if those are perceived as hostile, it may be extra-systemic. The Indian situation adds another dimension. Channels exist for an expression of support or discontent, and in such situations, conflict will be contained within the system unless the extent of perceived deprivation undermines its legitimacy. In the Indian case, the elec- toral process and devolution of authority for economic development to the district and block levels provide several potential levels of parti- cipation and fggi of authority. The electoral process probably hastens political mobilization. Promises made during campaigns elicit support. If they are not kept, one should expect support for opposition parties or candidates to rise over time. If, however, participants doubt they will receive benefits from any party then they may seek extra-legal means of expressing discontent. Thus, while an open electoral system may contain conflict in the short term, it will heighten conflict if benefits are not/cannot be distributed fairly widely through society. These are the main assumptions of the study. It should be clear that the concern here is not with the entire process of political and economic development: the urban and industrial sectors are omitted. 14 The study deals with a specific problem faced by Indian policy—makers in changing rural India. Its main findings should be relevant for situa— tions in which "production first" strategies are pursued with the assump- tion that resultant social and political changes can be treated sepa- rately and sequentially. They should be especially relevant if such strategies are pursued under resource constraints similar to those in India (a scarcity of land and capital and an abundance of labor). The study is derived from the central concepts of the development syndrome.2 The first idea borrowed from the literature is that a major difference between "traditional" and "modern" politics lies in the derivation of political legitimacy. Older forms of political authority derived theirs from transcendental or other sources (e.g., the divine right of kings). MOdern regimes at least try to gain (or justify) theirs from the governed. This implies a minimal amount of responsiveness to the citizens of a polity, but not necessarily representative government (though this is the case in India). It can mean that as governments seek to widen their support base by meeting demands from various groups, power becomes more widely dispersed.3 Central to the concept of responsiveness is the distribution of goods and services in society. Governments barter these in return for support. A result that may be at least minimally desired by government 1For a good example of "production first" strategies see the Asian Agricultural Survey (Manila: Asian Development Bank, 1968), passim. 2Leonard Binder §£_al., Crises and Sequences in Political Develop- ment (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971). See especially, "Crises of Political Development," by Binder, pp. 3-72. 3See S. N. Eisenstadt, Modernization, Protest, and Change (Engle— wood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1966); Binder, op; cit.; and John Kautsky, The Political Consequences of Mbdernization (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1972), passim. 15 is a Pareto Optimal situation, but that is seldom feasible since the goods and services are normally in short supply. Governmental capacity contributes to the establishment of distribution patterns. Capacity is at least partially dependent on bases of support. For example, if a government depends on a feudal landowning class for its power, then the dispersal of land and other agricultural resources to tenants will be limited by the landed aristocracy's interests. A mobilized peasantry may enable government to spread benefits more widely thus expanding its numerical base of support. By meeting peasant demands, however, power will also become more widely dispersed which in itself may place con— traints on future policy options. Under conditions of change, the question of distribution can reach crisis proportions when citizens are given and use their equal chances for participation. They are aware that by so doing they have the oppor- tunity to obtain benefits others in society have. Since all groups have interests -- some of which may be diametrically opposed to others -- not all will be fully satisfied. The resulting conflict is a normal part of the political process. Much of it may be over scarce economic resources but can also center on access to power and status. All this is obvious to the student of political science. Another point -- also familiar to political scientists -- is that it is government's role to mediate between conflicting groups. This can be done by (1) meeting demands where possible, (2) manipulating them, or substituting other desired goods for those demanded, or (3) by sup- pressing the groups, their demands or both.1 It is understood that the 1One might include Edelman's idea of the substitution of symbolic for tangible goods. See Murray Edelman, The Symbolic Uses of Politics 16 more developed a polity, the more capacity it has to use the two former options and they will be preferred. This is related to the idea of poli- tical development as characterized by responsive, if not representative, government.1 What is not so apparent to the political scientist is that strate- gies for economic and political development may be quite divergent, if not mutually exclusive phenomena. This calls for a discussion of what economic development often entails. The main aim of economic development is an increase in a nation's wealth (measured in a number of ways), with an assumed concomitant increase in its individual citizen's levels of well-being. These may be brought about by the application of modern technology to increase pro- duction and consumption in all sectors of society. Since this study deals with the agricultural sector of India, the discussion below cen- ters on its development. A first step is to distinguish "traditional" agriculture from that which is considered "modern".2 Typically, the former is characterized as labor-intensive, using "backward" technology resulting in low produc- tivity per unit of land and labor input. It is peasant farming: sub- sistence cultivation with minimal involvement in markets. Cultivation is a small scale family enterprise: for instance, in feudal systems, land is divided among tenants on the basis of what a family with animal (Urbana, Illinois: University of Illinois Press, 1967). See especially, Chapter 2, Part III. 1See Eisenstadt and Binder, op. cit. 2The author's doubts about the utility and validity of these con- cepts are strong as they are about anything suggesting a strict dichot- omy. They are suggestive of trends, however, and are used here to illu- strate the point and because they are commonly used in the literature. 17 power can manage.1 Modern agriculture conversely, utilizes capital- intensive, advanced technology, and participates fully in monetized mar- kets. While a family may still own and operate a farm, the scale of production is considerably expanded with the aid of modern mechanical implements replacing animal power. Productivity per unit of land and labor is assumed to be higher with the use of new scientific techniques. The modernization of agriculture implies a potential for high returns to investment through the production advantage of new seeds, chemical fertilizers, pesticides, irrigation, and farm machinery. Though the cost of inputs is higher, increased production brings the farmer greater profits than he could earn previously. However as improvements are introduced into situations where pressure on land is high and landownership is concentrated though cultivation is by tenants and/or agricultural labor, the latter two classes of persons are ren- dered obsolete. As the scale of production is raised by mechanization, landowners typically resume their farms for self-cultivation. Bio- chemical improvements can be used on any sized farm with the same "returns to scale"; large machines obviously cannot. Often as agricultural modernization occurs there is no additional land for displaced persons to colonize. One can argue that high tenancy rates are partially a result of population pressure on land. Also, technological change in agriculture (e.g., in the United States and Europe) arose from the necessity to feed growing populations at a time 1See Eric R. Wolf, Peasants, Foundations of Modern Anthropology Series (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1966), pp. 1-59. For modern agriculture, see Theodore Schultz, Transforming Traditional Agriculture (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1964). 18 when agricultural labor became expensive and scarce. Nonetheless, it always causes dislocation and affected persons move into urban areas seeking alternate employment. Industry is seldom able to utilize heavy flows of labor as it is a sector employing capital intensive technology. Dislocated peasants are often unskilled and illiterate. The result is urban slums. In cities migrants are exposed to new goods and amenities -- and particularly to the rising living standards of the middle and upper classes. Even factory workers through unions participate in the upward economic cycle. Thus it is that rising expectations combine with absolute deprivation to form a potential for revolution.1 Political science is not oblivious to these developments. It deals with them in the following manner. It accepts the theorem that economic change can cause instability. The literature traces causes of insta- bility to rapid transition that leads to anomie, displacement of persons from traditionally held occupations, rising expectations and greater inequalities in wealth and power, at least in the short run. A combi- nation of these leads to competition over power and wealth by mobilized groups where it may appear in the form of class or communal conflict. The process also mobilizes groups who may not have been participants in the political system, causing them to place additional demands on it. The strain of transition often occurs when political institutions them- selves are characterized by low levels of legitimacy.2 1See Eric Wolf, Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century (New York: Harper and Row, 1969); and Barrington Meore, Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966). This syndrome has, of course, been studied by many scholars and runs through the development literature, particularly anatomies of military coups d'etat in Africa and Latin America. 2See Karl W. Deutsch, "Social Mobilization and Political Develop- ment," in Jason Finkle and Richard Gable, eds., Political Development 19 The problem is that political scientists tend to agree with current methods and strategies of economic development, accepting them as inevit- able.1 That is, modern technology must be applied to production regard- less of social and political consequences. The divergence between the desired ends of political and economic development can be further clari- fied through an exploration of the implicationscflfthis strategy. Governments function with a scarcity of resources. As economic growth continues the overall resource pool may increase, but it is sel— dom sufficient. The economists argue that scarce resources should be invested in farmers and areas which have the highest growth potential.2 It takes considerably less to raise their productivity and the assump- tion is that there will be a "ripple effect" whereby other farmers and areas seeing higher profits will opt voluntarily over time for new tech— niques. The result is a policy favoring larger farmers over smaller ones, and wealthier regions over their more impoverished neighbors. The preferential treatment of larger farmers also has a political base. These are often citizens who can provide the most support -- both financial and numerical (through clients) -- for political leaders. and Social Change (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1971), pp. 384-405; Ted Gurr, "A Causal Medel of Civil Strife," American Political Science Review 62, 4 (December 1968),llO4-1124; and Huntington and Binder, op. cit. 1Or at least (which is less justifiable) we tend to assume that such things are someone else's responsibility, which leaves one with the conclusion that political and economic development cannot possibly occur together though history has plenty of cases to the contrary. 2See below: the discussion of the Intensive Agricultural Develop- ment Schemes in India. Additionally, see W. Arthur Lewis, Development Planning (New York: Harper and Row, 1966), pp. 58-61; John W. Mellor, The Economics of Agricultural Development (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1970 edition), pp. 296-298. 20 Where tenants and hired laborers constitute a high proportion of the agricultural classes, the control held by landowners over their economic well-being can be translated into political power. If, as in the Indian case larger landowners are also money-lenders, their control may extend over smaller owner-cultivators as well. For a government or political party with limited resources, this is perhaps the cheapest way to gain support at least in the short run. There are two areas of conflict arising out of this strategy: the first is potential inter-regional conflict. Those areas not receiving benefits may withhold support from ruling parties. Inter-regional con- flicts are beyond the scope of this study, but analyses of election results in India can lead one to conclude that they are a possibility.1 The second point of conflict is of concern here: inter-class con- flict. As mentioned above, tenants and labor normally are displaced in the course of agricultural modernization. Displacement is not confined to these two groups though they may be the first; in the longer run, the small and middle-sized owners also have to go.2 Large machines require larger farms: landowners who mechanize expand their farms to rational- ize their capital investment. As arable land is limited, they expand at the expense of small and middle owners. In primarily agricultural societies with the land distribution and population of India, this means the eventual dislocation of the majority of the total population. The 1This is dealt with at some length by Francine Frankel, India's Green Revolution: Economic Gains and Political Costs (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971). 2This should be familiar to readers of Moore, op. cit. and to those who have studied the deve10pment of U.S. agriculture during the 19208 and 308. 21 rate at which this occurs is directly related to the rate and scale of mechanization.1 Few countries are able to provide sufficient alternate employment for displaced persons which raises several questions. What is an opti- mum scale of farming given the costs and availability of manual and animal labor? Alternatively, given scarce capital, what are the costs of a capital-intensive agricultural sector to the overall economy? What is the magnitude of potential displacement, and what age the alternate employment possibilities for these displaced persons? Does the dis- placement mean a depression of the consumer market that would affect industrial growth? And finally, what are the political costs of dis- location? These political costs have two main sources: (1) landowners are no longer able to control the political choices and behavior of dis- placed tenants and laborers, and (2) deprivation may radicalize people. In the former case the costs of paying off displaced persons tend to be high, and in the latter, the legitimacy of the political system may come into question. There is a third alternative which may not entail direct political costs in the short to medium term: citizen apathy and des- pair. Such quiescence raises questions about the qualitative aspects of system stability. In relating this discussion to the Indian context, the following points need to be kept in mind. While the avowed ideology of the coun- try is to respond to people's needs to raise living standards for all, the government's perceived capacity leads it to meet demands of larger agriculturalists while manipulating those of smaller farmers, tenants 1See Frankel and Moore, op. cit.; and Kusum Nair, The Lonely Furrow: Farming in the United States, Japan, and India (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969). 22 and laborers. This suggests a political imperative preventing wider responsiveness. As long as landed groups are seen as able political mobilizers, responsiveness will be restricted. Even so, government has not totally ignored rural areas; indeed, it could not do so. Some benefits are required even with the support of landed interests to gain that of the smaller man. These benefits are mainly collective goods. Government has increased vastly, the range of services available particularly in health, education, and transport. If the dynamic of rural change outlined does obtain, however, personal deprivation will overshadow gains made by collective goods. Collective goods, however, are cheaper to distribute than the enactment of policies dealing with issues of landownership and agricultural growth with equal— ity. There are no groups who object to schools, clinics, and roads. That agrarian change is causing displacement and insecurity is clear in the data. First, as in other areas of India, tenants in the villages studied are faced with less employment and security of tenure. Because of the particulars of tenancy legislation discussed further in the study, they are unable to lease in land as readily as before. Aside from tenancy laws, agriculture has become a highly profitable enterprise. This means that landowners who previously saw their land as security, status symbol, and a means for securing their families' food, now view it as a commercial enterprise. Instead of leasing it to ten- ants and sharing the produce with them, they prefer to self-cultivate, hiring the fewest laborers possible. Active involvement in farming also gives the politically ambitious landowner control over inputs which in turn enhances his political stature. 23 Third, self-cultivation is possible with the availability of trac- tors capable of uniting large holdings into single cultivation units. This is not possible with animal power. Cultural restrictions which prohibit a Brahmin from touching a plow are overcome with discs and har~ rows attached to tractors.1 In both villages studied tractors are used primarily for plowing and hauling produce to market. Increasingly, how- ever, threshing and chaff cutting are also mechanically done. Tractor- ization of plowing itself eliminates the need for tenants and teams of oxen. It is debatable whether the increased man-hours necessitated by the more intensive cultivation of high yielding variety seeds means that more labor is hired. Fourth, even should middle and small farmers desire modern inputs their access to resources will be restricted by the skewed land distri- bution pattern. As resources are scarce, those with power and influ- ence can obtain them. Landownership is by and large, coincident with power and influence. It has historically been so and the present system tends to reinforce this. Government is the dominant distributor and the dispersal of inputs is unavoidably political. That is to be expected, but what is important is the socio-political setting in which they are distributed. It is the coincidence of landownership patterns with caste, status, wealth and political resources that makes the difference. At the time field work was conducted, smaller cultivators were mak- ing higher profits than before due to inflationary farm prices which rose due to the drought among other factors. This has to be seen as a 1Traditionally Brahmins may not touch the plow. For an interest- ing discussion of this, and other distinct caste practices, see Philip Mason, Patterns of Dominance (London: Oxford University Press, 1971), Chapter 7. 24 short-term windfall assuming that rises in basic food commodities Spark similar reactions in other sectors of the economy. Further there is a limit to how high prices can be permitted to rise given non-farm incomes. As agrarian change proceeds and food shortages are overcome, larger farmers will displace smaller ones as happened in the United States. At best small and marginal cultivators can remain as petty landowners who lease their lands to larger ones or who continue in sub- sidized subsistence farming protected by the state (similar to Mexican ejidatarios).1 How these issues relate to the political system is the fifth point. The data show that access to land and employment form the bases of poli- tical attitudes and activity. Political alternatives are limited for those with little or no land as they view Congress as the only party with the capacity to deliver benefits. This suggests that continued manipulation of demands will lead to increased levels of political frustration over time. Related to this is the assumption that nations such as India are not doomed to perpetual "backwardness". The argument does imply, how— ever, that if modernization is to mean the advancement of a few to the detriment of the many, stable political change is a moot point. Sta- bility in and of itself may be neither desirable nor undesirable; it depends on the value one assigns to any political system. It is of lSee V. M. Rao, "Village Lease Markets for Agricultural Land," Economic and Political Weekly, Review of Agriculture, IX, #26, June 29, 1974, p. Ar58 where he discusses the former possibility. For Mexico, see Rodolfo Stavenhagen, "Social Aspects of Agrarian Structure in Mexico," in Stavenhagen, ed., Agrarian Problems and Peasant Nevements in Latin America (Garden City: Anchor Books, 1970), pp. 225-270, passim. 25 concern here, however, in several ways: insofar as it is necessary for policy makers to formulate and implement policies, in relation to attaining the goals of better living standards for all, and insofar as the stated goals of the established system are threatened by the means chosen to reach them. After all, most of the scientific techniques for raising agricul- tural productivity (seeds and chemicals) can be utilized on virtually any sized plot. Evidence will be cited to show that the smaller farmer is more productive (per unit of land) than the larger because he has to depend on his small plot for his entire livelihood. Finally, moderni- zation cannot be equated with large agricultural production units in demographic situations similar to India's. The posited goals of better living standards (the necessary component being increased production) and socio-economic equality are not separate sequences of a change pro- cess. Means can be found whereby both can be attained or at least pur- sued concomitantly. This is the major task faced by social scientists concerned with policy making. The Agricultural Programs Before proceeding it is necessary to discuss the specific policies and programs enacted for agricultural change in India. The two villages studied were among the first in the state of Rajasthan to be included in the Intensive Agricultural Areas Programme. Agricultural change is assumed to be greater in areas covered by the intensive programs by both the Government of India and outside observers. The Intensive Agricultural Districts Programme (IADP) was the first concerted effort made by Government of India to increase food production 26 rapidly. Population growth combined with bad crop years from 1957-59 created food shortages. While agricultural production had been part of earlier community development schemes under the First and Second Five Year Plans, it became apparent that a concentrated effort would have to be made in the area of production alone simply to keep pace with an increasing population. The Intensive programs grew out of an approach suggested by a Ford Foundation team of experts.1 With little modification this has remained the basic guideline for agricultural modernization. It calls for an "integrated" or "package" approach to increasing production assuming that if farmers are provided with technical inputs along with the know- ledge for their use, production will increase. All farmers should adopt the more profitable techniques given that they are economically rational (or "profit-maximizers"). It is further assumed that backward technology has been the major constraint to higher production. Recognizing the immense under-utilization of human labor, the Team saw in the "package" approach a means of harnessing labor for productive ends by (l) intensifying cultivation and (2) creating greater employment through public works linked with production activities. The latter would include things such as minor irrigation and soil conservation projects. Finally, there was the view that resources should be concentrated in those areas where ... the combination of water, soil, and other resources indicate that food production increases will be the greatest."2 1The Agricultural Production Team sponsored by the Ford Foundation, Government of India, Report on India's Food Crisis and Steps to Meet It (New Delhi: Ministry of Food and Agriculture and Ministry of Community Development and Cooperation, April 1959). 2Ibid., p. 5 27 More effort should be concentrated on the most promising areas for wheat and rice production, i.e., those which had the most rapid rate of increase in the recent past, and which have also the highest potential for rapid large increases in the years immediately ahead... These areas will, the Team believes, increase India's food production more rapidly than others, if given allocations of fertilizers in combination with other improved practices, such as plant protection measures, improved seeds and water for irrigation. Attention to other areas should not be reduced. But in the national interest, the Team believes that increased effort should be,immediately directed to the most responsive areas.Ii(EmPhaSiS added) Specific recommendations spelled out the."package" itself. Two major areas of suggestions were (1) better economic and administrative arrangements and (2) the better use of physical and biological resources. In the first section of its report the Team called for price stabilization at remunerative levels. They suggested that Government set a procurement price for food grains well before the cropping season: To encourage increases in food-grain production, the cultivator should be assured of a price which will enable him to invest in fertilizer, seed and new equipment knowing that, with average crop con- ditions, he can repay any debts with the added income that results from adoption of improved practices. Such assurance would constitute n important incentive to increased production. Second, the Team pointed to the need for land reform which in their view meant establishing security of tenure rather than any redistribu- tion of land. The main argument was that security would enable culti- vators to invest in land improvements. As for the landless, the basic consensus assumed an insufficiency of land to assure all rural persons 1Ibid. 21bid., p. 25. 28 "adequately" sized farms. For the landless, employment would have to be found elsewhere and joint or cooperative farming arrangements might be made for farmers with marginal holdings. The fear that land redis- tribution could decrease productivity is clear: We recognize the need for considering programmes for the relief of those who have no land, and of those who cultivate too little land. But it is imperative to achieve this objective in ways that will not retard the increases in food_production which are vital to national welfare. Some progress can be made by arranging for reallocation, improvement and operation of potentially productive lands that are now idle, or are being used very ineffectively. Care should be exercised, however, so as not to break up arms that are efficiently and productively operated. Along with security of tenure, the Team recognized the need for consoli- dation of land holdings to encourage farmers to fully utilize their land and invest in improvements. The study also called for a number of institutional changes: the provision of adequate credit at reasonable rates through cooperatives, the evaluation of a farmer's credit-worthiness on the basis of produc- tion rather than landownership, and the realignment of governmental priorities to meet investments required in the agricultural sector. A part of this was to mobilize and involve local leaders and government functionaries in the field in the process of agricultural modernization to ensure implementation at the local level. Finally, an urgent plea was made for maximum inputs to be made into seed, fertilizer and pesticides development and manufacture. Better facilities were to be developed for food storage, marketing and 1Ibid., p. 29. 29 processing. This was the integral concept of presenting the farmer with his "package" of inputs. These recommendations were put into effect under what came to be known as the Intensive Agricultural Districts Programme (IADP). In the first year (1961-62), select villages in three districts were taken up on a pilot basis. Encouraged by early successes, thirteen additional districts were added. In 1964-65 a similar program was introduced into districts with good agricultural potential around the country. This was called the Intensive Agricultural Areas Programme (IAAP). Both villages studied for this project were among the first to be incorporated into it. Rather than concentrate on all-round agricultural development, this program focused on major crops in each area. According to both govern- ment and outside observers, however, the real distinction in agriculture has come with the High Yielding Varieties Programme (HYV), initiated in 1966-67. The HYV scheme went into effect in those districts already under the IAAP or IADP programs. The basic concept of the "package" still obtains but the main breakthrough is the technical one of hybridization of wheat and rice seed. The new dwarf varieties produce more than double that of indigeneous ones under optimal conditions. The potential of these seeds (the major successes are in wheat), and their consequential contribution to national food stocks in 1967-68 (a year with good rains), started talk of the Green Revolution not only in India, but throughout Asia. There are two thrusts to the HYV program. One is the increase in food production generally over any given cropping season. The other is the development of seeds of shorter duration which enable land use to be 30 intensified. Most of the seeds developed have a shorter maturation per- iod enabling farmers to take an additional crop each year. As laid out in the Fourth Five Year Plan, the following are the directions in which the schemes need further development: 6.18 The rate of increase in production of food- grains and major commercial crops envisaged is much higher than that accomplished in the past. Since there is very limited sc0pe for bringing additional land under cultivation, the strategy for realising the production targets is primarily dependent on intensive agriculture and consists of the following key elements: (1) continued expansion of irrigation facilities and reorientation of irrigation practices; optimum use of water, and in particular, inte- grated use of ground and surface water; improvement in the utilisation of existing irrigation potential through special pro- grammes; and measures to increase intensity of cropping; (2) expansion in the supply of fertilisers, plant protection materials, farm machinery and cre- dit; (3) full exploitation of the possibilities of raising yields opened by the new seed varie- ties in the case of cereals; (4) intensive efforts in selected suitable areas for raising the yield levels of major commer- cial crops; and (5) improvement in the agricultural marketing system in the interests of the producer along with assurance of minimum prices for major agricultural commodities. Government agencies increasingly sell only hybrid seeds. All of these need more irrigation, fertilizers and pesticides, which in turn require higher financial outlays by the farmer. Incentives are given to encourage adoption of the new techniques: government finances demonstrations cu: chosen farmers' fields, supplies are basically 1Government of India, Fourth Five Year Plan Draft, 1969-74 (New Delhi: The Planning Commission, March 1969), p. 113. 31 subsidized as government absorbs the costs of the extension delivery system. There are no taxes on agricultural income and land tax is nomi- nal.l Government's support prices for major food grains have risen con- sistently over the past five to six years and selling on the free market brings the producer a better rate.2 Loans and subsidies are available for the purchase of seed, fertilizers and farm machinery or other capi- tal inputs. The idea is to provide the farmer with every incentive to produce more. Prpgram Implementation The official distributive machinery functions as follows. Before each cropping season Village Level Workers (the lowest level of the extension staff) work with farmers in their "circle" (approximately 10 villages) to encourage utilization of new inputs. They forward an esti- mate of the amount of high yielding seeds required in their area to the Agricultural Extension Officers at the Panchayat Samiti (Development Block Office -— approximately 100 villages). The requests from all VLW's are combined and forwarded to the District Agricultural Officer from whom they go to the state level. It is the responsibility of the state to procure enough seed and other inputs. The State Ministry of Agriculture also sets a target number of hectares it would like to have 1In the year field work was conducted, government proposed a tax on income if a person's joint income from farming and other occupations exceeds Rs. 5,000/— ($666) annually. The highest tax paid in the vil- lages studies was Rs. 150/— ($20.00) for about 200 acres of which 40 were irrigated. 2For 1972-73 the wheat procurement price ranged from Rs. 75-85 per quintal depending on the variety. For 1973-74, it rose to Rs. 150/- ($20.00). Free market selling in May 1973 ranged from Rs. 110 (in the village) to Rs. 160 (in Jaipur city) ($14.66 to $21.33). In 1974, prices as high as Rs. 260/- ($34.66) were reported. 32 covered by the hybrids each season. These are based on the productive capacities of different regions and also on the aims of the National Five Year and Annual Plans. The targets are broken down for each area and field extension agents are expected to work with cultivators to encourage adoption to meet them. When received the inputs are sold through the Panchayat Samitis and farmers' cooperatives (the former carry seed and pesticides, the latter chemical fertilizers). Samitis are encouraged to conduct one or two- day "training camps" before each crapping season to keep farmers abreast of the latest recommendations and techniques. Farmers may also purchase seed directly from any outlet of the National Seeds Corporation (NSC) which is the major distributor of offi- cially certified seed. There are branches in both the cities of Jaipur and Bharatpur. Farmers may go to private seed stores or mail-order com- panies. Some stores sell NSC seed in addition to other stock. These also provide fertilizer and pesticides. All these supplies cost more through private channels though they are often more readily available. Finally, farmers can go directly to the major government seed production farms (though very few actually do so). The Agricultural Universities at Delhi (Puss), Ludhiana, Pantnagar, and Udaipur will sell directly to the cultivator. In order to meet the higher capital requirements of the new inputs, official credit is provided. Since nationalization in 1969, all banks have been encouraged to open rural branches for credit supply and small savings. The aim is to establish branches wherever. there is a revenue collection center. Interest rates at banks range from 8.5 percent for short-term loans of less than Rs. 2,000/- ($266.66) to 10.5 percent on 33 either short or long-term loans of Rs. 5,000/- ($666.66). Credit is available for a variety of purposes: small farm improvements, recurring expenses, major capital improvements and investments. Short-term loans repayable in six months to one year are obtainable for seed, fertilizers, pesticides, labor expenses and water or electri- city bills. Most of these are payments in kind. Indirect loans are given for capital improvements: new wells, the repair of old ones or the purchase and installation of pump sets. Payment for these is made to the contractor upon completion of the work. Medium-term loans are repayable between three and five years. In addition to capital invest- ments mentioned above, they also include things such as cement water channels, land levelling,fencing, and the development of ancillary industry such as dairy or poultry farming, orchards and fisheries. Finally, long-term loans repayable in five to seven years are mainly for the purchase of farm machinery. For these farmers are required to own a minimum amount of land: twelve acres for a fourteen horsepower tractor, and thirty acres for a fifty horsepower one, all of which must be irrigated.1 Besides banks, further short and medium term credit is provided by local cooperative societies. Anyone may join upon payment of a Rs. 11/~ ($1.47) fee. The bulk of the societies' capital is provided by govern- ment through the banks. Terms are similar to those at the banks but normally farmers are required to own 2.5 acres in order to qualify. 1Data are from interview between Barry H. Michie and the Bank Manager of the State Bank of Bikaner and Jaipur, Hanumangarh. 34 Interest rates are 9 percent for all types of loans. For large amounts of money, farmers need to go to the banks.1 Finally, as far as official sources of credit are concerned, farm- ers may go to the Land Mbrtgage Bank. Here both medium and long-term loans are available for capital improvements. The repayment periods are somewhat longer than at the regular banks and hence farmers seem to pre- fer using this source out of all official credit outlets. The best utilized source of credit despite the cheaper official funds, is the village money-lender. Credit from this source may be obtained in either cash, grain, or in the form of a monthly credit ceil- ing at the money-lender's general store for the purchase of items of everyday use. Repayment is normally in kind and is made after each har- vest. Interest rates vary in the two villages studied, but range from 12 to 50 percent. The role of the money-lender will be discussed in depth (Chapters III and IV). One more program for farmers should be noted briefly. It was to begin in Bharatpur in the year following field work (1973-74); lists of farmers to be included were being prepared. This program is to channel farm inputs to small and marginal farmers through the Small Farmers Development Agency and the Marginal Farmers and Agricultural Labourers Development Schemes. By the beginning of the Fourth Five Year Plan (1969) there was widespread recognition in official quarters that the gains of the Green Revolution technologies had accrued mainly to larger farmers holding high status and power in their communities. The aim of these schemes is to circumvent the socio-economic setting which prevents 1Data are from interviews with cooperative chairmen and secretaries in both villages. 35 wider dissemination of inputs and directly reach cultivators in the lower strata. The idea of the package still obtains and this program will be discussed further in the study.1 With this outline of the issues and programs in mind, we turn now to a description of the areas in which research was conducted, along with a brief discussion of the politico-administrative framework and the social setting. 1Data are from V. R. Gaikwad, Small Farmersp State Policy and Imple- mentation (Hyderabad, India: National Institute of Community Develop- ment, 1971), The "Introduction." CHAPTER II THE SETTING This chapter provides a background sketch of politics, administra- tive arrangements and a description of the districts and villages in which research was conducted. Though the following is a simplification of the overall social, economic and political scene, it should provide the necessary points of reference needed to interpret the findings pre- sented in subsequent chapters. The Politico-Administrative Framework Having gained independence from Britain in 1947, India became a republic in 1950. The country is a federation of states: most consti- tutional powers reside with her component states and residual powers belong to the center. India has a parliamentary form of government headed by an indirectly elected President. Elections for parliament and the state assemblies must be held at least every five years. Five general elections have been conducted on the basis of universal adult franchise since 1952.1 The last parliamentary elections were called one year early in 1971 while the state elections were held on time in 1972. 1The age of majority is 21 years. Elections took place in 1951-52, 1957, 1962, 1967, 1971 (parliament only - called early), and 1972 (states' assemblies - held on schedule). Several states have had mid- term polls with the resignations of their governments, and of course by-elections have been held to fill seats vacated by death, and other causes. 36 37 Turnout ranges from 45.7 percent for the first election to 61.33 per- cent in 1967.1 These are national figures; there is considerable varia- tion between the states. The central government has been formed by the Indian National Con- gress to date; the party has been a dominant force in Indian politics since its rise as the main nationalist movement in the early years of this century.2 Several states have had opposition governments of both the right and the left, and coalitions as well. The Congress itself has never won a majority of votes: its highest support was 47.78 percent in 1957, and this margin of plurality has declined since then.3 The frag- mented nature of the opposition permits it to retain control at the center. Each eligible voter elects his member of the state assembly and parliament directly. Approximately nine state constituencies make up one parliamentary one and there are between 700,000 and 1,000,000 per- sons in the latter. Districting is the prerogative of the Central Election Commision of India and major redrawing of boundaries takes place with each decennial census though changes can be made in between. Each constituency elects only one member. If the population of any constituency is 60 percent or more scheduled caste or tribe, it is 1Robert L. Hardgrave, Jr., India: Government and Politics in a Developing Nation (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1970), p. 186. 2The party split in 1969: the Prime Minister's wing is called the Congress-Reorganization wing, and the old Congress is referred to as Congress Party-Opposition, or in common political parlance, "The Syndicate". Each contests elections as separate parties. 3Indian Election Commission, Report on the Fourth General Elections in India, Vol. I (New Delhi: Government of India Press, 1968), pp. 94- 95 (adapted). 38 reserved for candidates of those communities regardless of party affil- iation.1 The logistics of conducting elections in India are complex. It takes in excess of a million and a half persons in various capacities. Polling booths are situated so that no person has to travel more than three miles. The first elections took more than four months to complete, the ones held in 1967 were completed in one week and less time is required now. The eligible electorate in 1971-72 was 273,134,889 per- sons. Voters queue at the station, and a polling officer checks each voter's identity slip against his name on the electoral roll. The voter's finger is then marked with indelible ink, and he receives two bal- lots, pink for the assembly, white for the Lok Sabha (parliament). He marks both ballots secretly with a rubber stamp on the symbol of the candidate for whom he wishes to vote, folds the ballots, and drops them into the box. Although the procedure is involved, the number of invalid votes has been relatively small, averaging 3 to 4 percent of the total cast. The whole procedure is scrutinized by polling agents representing each candidate. Their presence and assistance also serve to iden— tify voters and prevent impersonations. 1The scheduled groups are so-called "backward" communities granted certain socio-political privileges in order to integrate them into the mainstream of Indian life. These groups have traditionally been dis- criminated against: either outcastes or tribal, non-Hindu groups. The Schedule is a Census device for identifying such communities and now is the only published record maintained of caste or tribe. The only other place where caste is listed is in land records. This is for purposes of making special land allotments to outcastes and tribal groups. It also helps the researcher to identify farmers since nor— mally they would list only their first, and father's names both of which might be shared by several other persons. Of course the latter rationale is my own. 2Election Commission of India, Report on the Fifth General Election in India, Narrative and Reflective Part (Delhi: Government of India Press, 1973), p. 56. 3Hardgrave, op. cit., pp. 164-65. 39 Though over one hundred parties have contested elections since 1952, few are of national strength and even fewer have lasted through all five elections. Tables 2.1 and 2.2 show the main ones with their relative strengths both at the state and national levels. Relatively few constituencies (especially rural ones) have more than three-way con- tests in which all parties are serious contenders. Both villages stud- ied were two-party constituencies with splinter elements of others. India has twenty-three states, the boundaries of which coincide with those of major cultural/linguistic groups (see Figure 2.1). The state of Rajasthan where field work was done, assumed its present shape in 1956 with the merging of three regions: Rajputana (composed largely of the Rajput princely states), the Matsya Union (including parts of Shekawati and northeastern princely states), and Ajmer which had been directly under British rule. It is the second largest state in the area covering 13,212,956 square miles. The total population is 25,765,806 persons with a density of 194 persons per square mile.1 There are twenty-six districts in Rajasthan. Each is divided into a number of tehsils (revenue units), and panchayat samitis (development blocks) (see Figure 2.2). The tehsil staff consists of a tehsildar and a number of patwaris each of whom is responsible for the maintenance of land records and revenue collection in his "circle" of villages. The tehsildar is also responsible for certain law and order issues and for the collection of basic data such as crop estimates, rainfall, etc. He is asked to help during elections and the taking of each decennial cen- SUS . 1Data are from Census of India, 1971, Series 18, Rajasthan, Part II-A, (General Population Tables - abstracted from several tables). 40 TABLE 2.1 THE DISTRIBUTION OF CANDIDATES, SEATS, AND VOTES IN LOK SABHA ELECTIONS, 1952-67 Number of Number of 2 Z Parties Candidates Seats Won of Seats of Votes 1952 Congress 472 364 74.4 45.00 C.P.I. 49 16 3.3 3.30 Socialist Party 256 12 2.5 10.60 Kisan Mazdoor Praja Party 145 9 1.8 5.80 Hindu Mahasabha 31 4 0.8 0.95 Jana Sangh 93 3 0.6 3.10 Ram Rajya Parishad 55 3 0.6 2.03 Republican Party 27 2 0.4 2.36 Other parties 215 35 7.2 11.10 Independents 521 _41_ 8.4 15.80 Total 489 1957 Congress 490 371 75.1 47.78 C.P.I. 108 27 5.4 8.92 Praja Socialist Party (S.P. and K.M.P.P.) 189 19 3.8 10.41 Jana Sangh 130 4 0.8 5.93 Republican Party 19 4 0.8 1.50 Hindu Mahasabha 19 1 0.2 0.86 Ram Rajya Parishad 15 -- -- 0.38 Other parties 73 29 5.9 4.81 Independents 475 _;23 7.9 19.39 Total 494 1962 Congress 488 361 73.1 46.02 C.P.I. 137 29 5.9 9.96 Swatantra 172 18 3.6 6.80 Jana Sangh 198 14 2.8 6.44 Praja Socialist Party 166 12 2.4 6.84 D.M.K. (Tamilnadu only) 18 7 1.4 2.02 Socialist Party 107 6 1.2 2.49 Republican Party 69 3 0.6 2.78 Ram Rajya Parishad 35 2 0.4 0.55 Hindu Mahasabha 32 l 0.2 0.44 Other parties 64 14 2.9 4.31 Independents 497 27 5.5 12.27 Total 494 41 TABLE 2.l--Continued Number of Number of ‘i? 2 Parties Candidates Seats Won of Seats of Votes 1967 Congress 516 283 54.42 40.73 Swatantra 179 44 8.46 8.68 Jana Sangh 250 35 6.73 9.41 D.MQK. (Tamilnadu only) 25 25 4.80 3.90 C.P.I. 109 23 4.42 5.19 Samyukta Socialist Party 122 23 4.42 4.92 C.P.I. (M.) 59 19 3.65 4.21 Praja Socialist Party 109 13 2.50 3.06 Republican Party 70 l 0.19 2.48 Other parties 65 19 3.65 3.67 Independents 865 __35 6.73 13.75 Total 520 Source: Adapted from W. H. Morris-Jones, Government and Politics in India (London: Hutchinson, 1966), pp. 163-66, and from the Indian Election Commission, Report on the Fourth General Elections in India, Vol. 1 (New Delhi: Government Press, 1968), pp. 94-95. TABLE 2.2 THE DISTRIBUTION OF CANDIDATES, SEATS, AND VOTES IN STATE ASSEMBLY ELECTIONS, 1952-67 Number of Number of Z Z Parties Candidates Seats Won of Seats of Votes 1952 Congress 3,153 2,246 68.4 42.20 Socialist Party 1,799 125 3.8 9.70 C.P.I. 465 106 3.2 4.38 Kisan Mazdoor Praja Party 1,005 77 2.3 5.11 Jana Sangh 717 35 1.1 2.76 Ram Rajya Parishad 314 31 0.9 1.21 Hindu Mahasabha 194 14 0.4 0.82 Republican Party 171 3 0.1 1.68 Other parties and independents 7,492 635 19.3 32.14 Total 3,283 1957 Congress 3,027 2,012 64.9 44.97 C.P.I. 812 176 5.7 9.36 42 TABLE 2.2~-Continued Number of Number of Z Z Parties Candidates Seats Won of Seats of Votes 1957 (cont.) Praja Socialist (S.P. and K.M.P.P.) 1,154 208 6.7 9.75 Jana Sangh 584 46 1.5 3.60 Ram Rajya Parishad 146 22 0.7 0.69 Republican Party 99 21 0.7 1.31 Hindu Mahasabha 87 6 0.2 0.50 Other parties and independents 4,863 611 19.7 29.81 Total 3,102 1962 Congress 3,062 1,984 60.2 43.53 C.P.I. 975 197 6.0 10.42 Praja Socialist Party 1,149 179 5.4 7.69 Swatantra 1,012 170 5.2 6.49 Jana Sangh 1,135 116 3.5 5.40 Socialist Party 632 64 1.9 2.38 D.M.K. (Tamilnadu only)* 142 50 -- -- Ram Rajya Parishad 99 13 0.4 0.29 Republican Party 99 11 0.3 0.56 Hindu Mahasabha 75 8 0.2 0.24 Other parties and independents 5,313 555 16 8 23.00 Total 3,297 1967 Congress 3,443 1,694 48.59 39.96 Jana Sangh 1,607 268 7.70 8.78 Swatantra 978 257 7.37 6.65 Samyukta Socialist Party 813 180 5.16 5.19 D.M.K. (Tamilnadu only)* 174 138 3.96 4.34 C.P.I. (M.) 511 128 3.67 4.60 C.P.I. 625 121 3.47 4.13 Praja Socialist Party 768 106 3.04 3.40 Republican Party 378 23 0.66 1.53 Other parties 430 195 5.59 4.75 Independents 6,774 376 10.79 16.67 Total 3,486 *In Tamilnadu in 1962 the D.M.K. gained 24.3 percent of the assembly seats and 27 percent of the vote. In 1967 it secured 59.4 percent of the seats and 44.66 percent of the vote. Source: Ibid. 43 FIGURE 2.1 RAJASTHAN STATE “amass \\ u Hanumum - SOURCE: Census of India, 1961, Vol. XIV, Rajasthan, Part V-A (Jaipur, India: Census of Rajasthan, 1965). FIGURE 2.2 INDIA: ELECTORAL-ADMINISTRATIVE STRUCTURES ELECTORAL SYSTEM President 7' ’9 N' / I ‘ / g ‘ \ / Parliament \ ’ \ I Lok Sabha \ Rajya Sabha (House of (Council of the People) States) A A I State Assembly “9(Vidhan Sabha) District Council (Zilla Parishad) 4* I Block Council (Panchayat Samiti) an I I Village'Council (Gram Panchayat) Electorate Key: Directly elected :——-) Indirectly elected : - - - - 9 ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM National Ministries State Ministries District Administration Tehsil (Revenue Office) Development Block Village Level Workers 45 The panchayat samitis have responsibility for local development and cover an area of approximately 100 villages. Government provides a technical staff from the civil services: agricultural, nutrition, and plant protection extension workers, village level workers, school teachers and administrators. It also provides financial and material resources to meet the needs of development schemes. A Block Deve10pment Officer is the senior administrator of the samiti and he may be a generalist administrator or increasingly is drawn from the ranks of technicians from the Ministry of Agriculture. The administrative staff acts on the recommendation of the samiti itself: an indirectly elected council composed of the chairmen of dir- ectly elected village councils (gram penchayats). The sarpanchas com- posing the samiti choose a chairman from among themselves called the pradhan. Where the pradhan and/or members of the samiti are strong per- sonalities, one finds active participation in developmental affairs. All too often, however, the samiti acts as a rubber stamp for govern- mental programs interfering only if an officer offends local sensiti- vities or leaders. Samitis and gram penchayats both have taxation powers but as is often the case anywhere, there is reluctance to use them and to rely on government funds. Each pradhan is a member of his district level council (£1113 parishad) and here again, the pradhans elect their chairman who is called a pramukh. Local government thus is indirectly elected. Though village council members are to be elected every five years, the last elections were held nine years ago. Each time an election is scheduled, it is either a year of drought, or there is a war with Pakistan. It is felt that such "unnatural situations" might detract from the fairness 46 of elections.1 Local elections are fought on a non-partisan basis though in reality political parties are openly interested in their out- come. Villagers tend to identify panchayat members by their party affiliation. The Districts Jaipur and Bharatpur districts were selected for field study (see Figure 2.1). They were among the first to be incorporated into the Intensive Agricultural Areas and High Yielding Varities Programmes. Two main constraints led to their selection from a total of eleven possible districts.2 The first was the two year drought: the districts of Udaipur, Bhilwara, and Chittorgarh as well as Pali, the original Inten- sive Agricultural Districts Programme district, were affected to the point that famine—relief and related considerations would have over- shadowed all other variables. Second, due to the Indo-Pakistani war of 1971, the government of Rajasthan requested that research not be con- ducted in border areas which eliminated Sri Ganganagar, perhaps the most productive district in the state. Kota district, also very productive, had to be omitted because of certain political questions posed by the presence of an atomic reactor. The remaining districts were Jaipur, Bharatpur, Alwar and Jhalawar. The first three are contiguous with Alwar situated between the other two. Agriculturally and socially Alwar overlaps with Jaipur and Bharatpur. Jhalawar was not included partially because of drought and also due to anticipated linguistic problems. 1There was drought the year field work was conducted and the pre- vious year there had been the war with Pakistan as a result of the Bangladesh conflict. 2Census of India, op. cit. 47 The population of Bharatpur district is 1,490,206 persons with all save 205,095 being classified as rural residents. The total area is 3,124.7 square miles with an overall density of 476.6 persons per square mile.1 Bharatpur was added to Rajasthan in 1956. It is one of the most agriculturally productive areas of Rajasthan: most persons would name it and Sri Ganganagar as the two most "developed districts" in the state. Rainfall is greater than in other districts: around 60 inches per year. Jaipur district has the state capital in Jaipur city, a place of considerable tourist fame. It is a fairly large district covering 5,405.4 square miles with a total population of 2,482,385 persons and a density of 455.13 per square mile. Though parts of the district are arid, other areas such as the portion in which field work was conducted have irrigation and are good agricultural regions. Rainfall is less than in Bharatpur: around 35 inches in a normal year. Both districts used to be independent princely states of British India. Internal affairs were conducted by the traditional rulers (£2125), under the watchful eyes of British commissioners. Each state had separate treaties with the British who controlled foreign affairs, defense and related matters. There was only an indirect link between reform groups in the states and the Congress nationalist movement until fairly late in the 19308 and 408.3 The reform groups called praja 1Ibid. 2Ibid. 3Informal links with the Congress were formed fairly early, but no formal ties were created partially due to the raja's antipathy to the nationalists in general and consequent suppression of anything vaguely related to it. 48 mandals, merged mainly with the Congress party after independence.1 Currently, the major political forces are those of the Congress (R) and the right-wing Swatantra and Jan Sangh parties.2 The former ruling families of both districts have been involved in the Swatantra party: the village studied in Jaipur had elected a Congress member of the state assembly for the first time in 1972, and the member from Bharatpur was the younger brother of the erstwhile maharajah though the village itself was a Congress village.3 Land relations in the two areas vary in their legal aspects but are similar in the resulting social stratification. Traditionally, Rajasthan had two dominant systems of land tenure. Large tracts were under what was known as the jagirdari system. Grants covering anywhere from a few to many villages would be given to subjects of £3135 for services rendered. Though there have been legal questions raised as to the actual ownership of these areas, the jagirs provided income both for the intermediary landowners (jagirdars), and through them to the state. Land in each jegi£_was farmed by tenants who normally had hereditary, but oral leases. 1These movements fought mainly for constitutional reforms in the princely states and only in the latter years linked these with a demand for independence. They wanted the formation of representative state assemblies and to limit the rajas' powers. The movements were largely urban. See K. L. Kamal, Party Politics in an Indian State (Delhi: 8. Chand, 1969), and Richard Sisson, The Congress Party in Rajasthan (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1972). 2The Swatantra party was formally dissolved in 1974 -- former mem- bers are to work for a non-Communist, anti-Congress coalition group. The Congress (R) is Indira Gandhi's party - see above, p. 37, footnote. 3A11 privileges and titles of the former ruling families have been abolished along with compensation purses paid to them after indepen- dence when they lost revenue from their former principalities. 49 The other main form of agrarian organization was land directly owned by the state called khalsa. The village in Jaipur district was one such area. Here tenants were given rights of cultivation directly by the royal family of that particular state. Again, most leases were hereditary, but oral. In between these two were special land grants given to priestly families or traders. A number of Brahmins who owned land in the Jaipur village had got it from such mgefi grants; these were essentially reli- gious trusts enabling the priests to earn their livelihood. Since Brahmins are forbidden by custom to touch a plow, these lands were also farmed by tenants. Certain other areas of the state were under "permanent peasant settlements": ryotwari settlements. Neither area studied came under this. Permutations of these main types abounded with small legal dif- ferences between them. The major point to be remembered is that most areas were under tenant cultivation with revenue paid (in either cash or kind), to intermediary landowners or directly to the state. Aside from land taxes, tenants might also be requred to furnish free labor to either the state, landlord, or both, to pay extra cesses on ceremonial occasions, use of common grazing lands, etc. The amounts and kinds of taxes varied throughout what is now Rajasthan, however, the consensus is that they were uniformly onerous burdens for tenants to bear. Shortly after independence, legislation was passed to eliminate the intermediary landlords: jagirdars in Rajasthan, zamindars, 1Data are from Dhool Singh, A Study of Land Reforms in Rajasthan, Report of a Survey Sponsored by the Research Programmes Committee (New Delhi: Government of India, Planning Commission, 1964), Chapters 2-5. 50 elsewhere.1 They were permitted to retain "sufficient" land for self- cultivation, but the purpose was to grant ownership to tenants. These and the former jagirdars are now classifed as "state's tenants," or khatedars. Virtually all ownership rights including those of sale and mortgage have been granted to the khatedars though there is debate on the land's actual ownership which some legal scholars maintain is vested in the state. The actual redistribution of land is recognized by both official and private observers to have been minimal. Former landlords have kept the bulk of their holdings either by dispersing ownership among members of their rather extensive families, by sharecropping rather than leasing land, or by buying tractors to unify their cultivation units under one or two managers. The Gini Index of Land Equality in India did not change much after reforms were implemented: .63 in 1954 (based on 1951 data), and .59 in 1961 (1961).2 A better reflection of reality which accounts for dispersed land titles lies in the following data: Of all cultivating households, 64.4% operate only 19.82 of all farmed land, and all of these units are under five acres. As regards ownership, 71.95% of all landowners own 19.98Z of the land with all holdings under five acres and average size of holdings is 3.58 acres.3 1In Rajasthan there were a series of specific laws passed including the main ones of Rajasthan Land Reforms and Resumption of Jagirs Act, 1952, and the Rajasthan Zamindari and Biswedari Abolition Act, 1959. 2Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968), p. 383, Table 6.2. 3Adapted from the National Sample Survey, Seventeenth Round, Reports #162 (1970), pp. 48 and 52, Tables 12 and 13; #144 (1968), p. 13 Table 2; and #162 (1970), p. 16, Table 16 (Delhi: Manager of Publi- cations, 1968 and 1970). Taken from Barry H. Michie, "Variations in Economic Behaviour and the Green Revolution," Economic and Political 51 Since the Jaipur village was a khalsa one, a majority of culti- vators are small owners. These former Jaipur state tenants now have khatedari rights. Even so, there are several larger landowners with holdings in excess of fifty acres: these have been acquired either as ‘mgafi grants, through money-lending foreclosures or purchase over the past ten years. Land ceilings (until the year of study) were 35 acres for irrigated land (more for inferior farms) but it is clear that to ignore ceilings is relatively simple.1 The Bharatpur village had been under the jagirdari system. Com— pared with the Jaipur village, more farmers fall into the large farmer category of the sample. Several own in excess of two to three hundred acres spread over several villages. The titles are dispersed to circum— vent jagirdari abolition laws. The villages were chosen from among those in each district which first came under the intensive programs.2 In Jaipur several of these are now municipalities and two are almost suburbs of Jaipur city with rapidly expanding industrial sectors making agriculture almost secon- dary. Because of their proximity to the city, much of the land is owned Weekly, Vol. VIII, #26, Review of Agriculture (June 1973)._PP‘ A'69‘ 70. The varied findings suggest that rather than landownership, anyone interested in selecting samples of agriculturalists should use the Oper- ational farm unit. The largest farmer found in the land records in both villages "owned" only forty acres, half of which were irrigated. His operational unit, however, was over five hundred acres over three or four villages and all were operated by him and his three sons. 1For a further discussion about this see Dhool Singh, op. cit., Chapter 11,_g£ passim. 2When the schemes were started pilot villages were chosen in each district. Every year since then, additional ones are added as their potential and government's inputs along with political expediency have allowed. 52 by urban persons who are "gentlemen farmers" or absentee landlords who are not directly relevant to the study. Some villages close to urban areas tend to concentrate on truck farming which is also not directly relevant to the Green Revolution syndrome. The situation in Bharatpur is similar with one additional problem. Major land grants have been made to retired military personnel and former retainers of the erstwhile Bharatpur royal family. Many of the grants are close to Bharatpur city so that the grantees tend to dominate the life in those villages. Since they are not really a part of village society, their presence makes for a set of variables not present else- where. Finally, in both areas, villages close to cities make it easy for laborers to migrate for work during agriculturally slack seasons. While this might be interesting by itself, most areas do not have such options so readily available. In order to get a modicum of representa- tiveness, villages further away from cities were chosen. Even in these, as will be seen further in the study, there was some out-migration. Both villages have a fairly wide spread of cultivating communities which provides a control variable of caste. They have been judged by both government and university personnel1 as villages with good agri- cultural potential and represent areas that have made considerable pro- gress over the past five to six years (approximately the duration of the intensive programs). These are also villages known to be receptive to outsiders -- no small necessity in field work. The following sections 1The reference is to district-level government personnel and those of the University of Udaipur Extension Services in Bharatpur. See the Acknowledgements. 53 give a short description of each village. The names used here and fur- ther in the study for villages, farmers and leaders are, of course, not the real ones. Hanumangarh Hanumangarh served as "headquarters" for the field study. Situated seventeen miles to the northeast of Jaipur city on a paved road, it is well connected with both Jaipur and the market town of Dausa by buses which run every half hour during peak times and every two hours during the middle of the day. Of a total population of around 5,000, 3,000 persons live in the village proper. The rest reside in 32 hamlets scat- tered within a radius of four miles. It is thus a very large village bordering on the size of a municipality. As most of the inhabitants are agriculturalists, it retains its census classification as a village.1 Historically, Hanumangarh is of some interest to the development of Jaipur state. It was one of the early capitals having been taken by the Rajput prince Dula Rai about one thousand years ago from the "tribal" Minas. The village is built against a hillside and is dominated by a crumbling Rajput fort dating back to the 16th century. The original Mina fortress atop the hill is gone save for rudiments of the founda— tions. While Minas still constitute a sizable proportion of the popu- lation, the fort stands as a lonely monument to Rajput glory. There are now only about four Rajput families (all later migrants), and all of these save one are in rather impoverished circumstances. 1The census guidelines for classifying settlements as municipalities or villages is dependent on the p0pulation size, its density, and the proportion whose major occupation is agriculture. Rumor had it that village leaders were interested in keeping Hanumangarh's village classi— fication in order to retain rural development funds. 54 Over the years Hanumangarh probably served as a marketing and administrative center for the surrounding villages. The central street is bordered by multi-storied stone and mortar houses dating back several centuries. The ground floors of these were shops of various kinds until recently. Mast of them are locked now -- the advent of paved roads and bus service has made it possible and more economical for villagers to buy provisions in Jaipur. There are still a few cloth and provision stores. One "general store" carries items of daily use: tea, soap, cigarettes, cooking and kerosene oil, spices, and sticky sugar candies. Virtually any item may be ordered through the store but all can be had more cheaply in Jaipur. There are at least four small flour mills and two licensed country liquor shops. Trading families save for those in the grain trade or who are seriously developing their farms are leaving the village. Some lease their homes to government officers posted there. Commercially, Hanumangarh is a dying village -- agriculture is its domi- nant occupation. Reflecting perhaps the increasing importance of agriculture, there has been a growth of developmental agencies in the village. Besides its original designation as a tehsil, it is also a panchayat samiti head- quarters with three agricultural extension officers instead of the nor- mal two. There is a health sub-center staffed by a doctor, pharmacist, and nurse-mid-wife. Aside from curative aspects of health care, the center has a village—level health worker in charge of malaria, small-pox and other epidemic control schemes, and a male and female family planning extension team. Nutrition education and child care is the responsibility of the Lady Nutrition Extension Officer who is part of the samiti staff, and her subordinate, Lady Village Level Worker. The government offices 55 have their full complement of workers, which is not always the case elsewhere. Hanumangarh's educational needs are met by two primary schools (one for girls only), a middle (grade), and higher secondary school. The latter two are co-educational, limiting girls' enrollment. Initial talks were reportedly started to open a college for which rumor had it that the former maharaja was willing to donate a hunting lodge on the outskirts of the village. Not many young persons go on to higher educa- tion; those who do, enroll at one of Jaipur's colleges affiliated with the University of Rajasthan. Law and order is the responsibility of the local police station (thang). There is a small overnight lockup for arrested persons to wait until they are taken to Jaipur. The £hag§_has another lockup too: this one for stray animals to be impounded until their owners pay the required fines. As was mentioned above, the tehsil offices also aid the police in the maintenance of civil order. In addition to these agencies, Hanumangarh has a Department of Forests' Range Office in charge of maintaining certain grazing areas. This office is trying to re-forest the surrounding hills which were denuded by lumber contractors about twenty years ago. There is also an office of the State Excise Department whose primary purpose is the col- lection of taxes levied on the production of tobacco. Finally, Hanumangarh has a branch of the State Bank of Bikaner and Jaipur and is headquarters for the local cooperative society. It is a major admini- strative center. Hanumangarh is overwhelmingly Hindu in its religious makeup. There are fewer than ten Muslim families and no Jains, Sikhs or any other 56 religious groups. The Mina community mentioned above as the original ruling group is classified in the Census Schedule as a "tribe". While it may have had a tribal organization several hundred years ago, there is no longer any sociological reason for it to be classified as such any more. Minas are often referred to as "criminal tribes" as one group was involved traditionally in animal husbandry and developed a reputation for cattle and camel rustling. Whatever the origin of their inclusion in the Schedule, they are keen to retain it as it entails benefits such as land allotments, scholarships, and reserved seats in government employment and on all elected bodies. A clue to the real social status of Minas lies in their acceptance by other caste Hindus as a distinct caste of approximately Sudra status. It is not the purpose of this study, however, to debate issues raised by the Schedule.1 Occupationally there are four clusters of castes and each cluster is about the same size. At the t0p are the Brahmins and Baniyas and as stated, they control sizable proportions of land and money—lending. Only one group of Brahmins farms directly: the Haryana Brahmins, some of whom are in the sample. Next, there is a group of owner-cultivators: mainly Minas, Gujjars and Malis. Save for Gujjars, most of these fall in the small to medium range of farmers. Third, one finds the artisans: potters, barbers, carpenters and blacksmiths. Mbst of these are land- less or at best may own marginal farms. A number are also tenants. Finally, there are the outcastes or Harijans: Raigers, Khatiks, and Balais. Each of these is a distinct caste with its own position in the 1For an explanation of the Schedule, see above, p. 38, footnote. A more detailed explanation of caste follows in Chapter VII; here it should be noted that the term as used refers to jati (sub-caste), rather than the four-fold varna scheme. 57 ritual hierarchy defining marriage and commensal relations with the others. These provide the bulk of tenants and laborers (see Table 2.3). TABLE 2.3 HIERARCHY 0F CASTES IN HANUMANGARH AND SHIVPURA* Hanumangarh Shivpura Purohit Brahmins (priests and landowners) Haryana Brahmins (landowners) Rajputs ("warriors" and landowners) Baniyas (traders, money-lenders, landowners) Malis (farmers) Gujjars (farmers and animal husbandry) Minas (farmers and animal husbandry) Khatti (carpenters) Kumhars (potters) Nais (barbers) Lohars (blacksmiths) Raigers (laborers, leatherworkers) Khatiks (laborers, leatherworkers, herders, butchers) Balais (laborers, leatherworkers) Bhangi (sweepers) Purohit Brahmins (priests) Baniyas (traders, money- lenders) Jats (farmers) Ahirs (farmers) Yadavs (farmers) Garghariya (herders and farmers) Kohlis (petty traders, weavers) Chamars (laborers, leather- workers) Bhangis (sweepers) Muslim Castes: Manihar (traders, bangle makers) Telis (oil pressers, laborers) *This is a highly general ranking: the middle levels vary according to the group asked to rank itself, as each tends to put itself above the others. There are two distinct farming regions in the village. land is arid with a water table of 80-120 feet. 0n the east Irrigation is rela- tively limited and is done from open dug wells, a number of which are fitted with electric or diesel pumping in Jaipur district due to bedrock. sets.l Tubewells are expensive In this area even dug wells are 1These are five to six horsepower centrifugal pumps costing around Rs. 3,500 ($466.00). 58 costly because of the water's depth. Most crops are rain-fed. Animal husbandry is the main cash earner and grain cultivation is seen pri- marily as a means of feeding one's family. Due to continuous over- grazing by sheep, goats, cattle and buffalos over the past several hun- dred years, the soil is badly eroded. Gullies of ten to sixty feet cries-cross the landscape. Reclamation work has been marginal. People depend on government and drought years for conservation projects to be undertaken as part of famine relief work.1 The best land is under cultivation and is irrigated if possible. Landholdings are larger here. The second farming region is fortunate to have a higher water table of thirty to sixty feet. The wells recharge quickly due to a nearby natural reservoir which supplies water to Jaipur. No irrigation is per- mitted from this though it was originally dammed for that purpose. Most plots are smaller here but almost all can take two crops a year and even three in some cases. Soils in both areas of Hanumangarh are of a light, sandy-loam var- iety with little moisture-retaining capacity. The main crop as in most parts of India is taken in the monsoon season (July to September/ October). It is rain-fed: even if the rains fail, few farmers will use their wells for supplementary irrigation fearing there will be insuffi- cient water for the winter crOp. This crop consists mainly of bulrush millet (pennisetum typhoideum). Some farmers grow maize and vegetables 1If an area is declared to be under famine, public works are begun on roads, conservation, irrigation, etc. Affected persons, landowners and landless alike may work on these for wages paid half in cash and half in grain. Much work could be done by individual farmers to build short walls around their fields (called bundhs) to prevent erosion. The government encourages this with little effect. Several fields the author saw decreased several feet in size each year because of a lack of bundhs. 59 as supplementary crops. The millet forms the basic component of most people's diet though wheat is the preferred grain. Crops for the winter season are sown from late October through November. The acreage is less than that planted during the monsoon because irrigation is required. Where this is available, farmers plant wheat, barley and vegetables. Where it is limited or non-existent, cer- tain varieties of barley and gram may be sown. Mbst farmers are mainly grain cultivators. The vegetables are for family consumption and per- haps a little extra cash. Normally one finds a few beds alongside a well. Only two persons interviewed cultivated vegetables as a main crop. Shivpura Shivpura presents a rather different set of circumstances. The village is sixteen miles from the nearest city, Bharatpur, which is also the district headquarters and tehsil town. The communication and ser- vice facilities are not as extensive here. After travelling ten miles on a paved road, one turns off onto a path of sorts formed by bullock cart ruts leading to the village. Plans have been on the books since the First Five Year Plan to build the road and this is a major election issue every five years. Shivpura is smaller than Hanumangarh with a population of around 1,400 persons. All inhabitants live in one central settlement rather than in hamlets. Local history has it that one of the kings of 1In view of the fact that Jaipur was so accessible, it is surpris- ing that more did not cultivate vegetables which are highly profitable: much more so than grain. When asked, most farmers maintain they take too much work and that there are no adequate marketing facilities. 60 Bharatpur had twenty-two sons. Since only the eldest could inherit his father's throne, the rest were given grants of several villages each from which they were to provide fOr themselves and the state. Shivpura was made a headquarters by one of the sons and today all the village Thakurs claim descent from him.1 They are the main landowners and their holdings are far more extensive than anyone's in Hanumangarh. The largest farmer here owns around 500 acres over several villages. Shivpura has a farmers' cooperative and is the headquarters for a Village Level Worker. Funds were raised by the villagers for his house in order to persuade government to post one there. Kumher is head- quarters for both the_panchayat samiti and the health center. Shivpura residents commute to Kumher for official business on a very old bus which goes in the morning and returns by evening. The village has a small dispensary run by a pharmacist, a lady family planning worker, and a doctor of the traditional Ayurvedic school of medicine. Education has found the full support of Shivpura inhabitants. They raised funds to build the middle and high schools. The primary school presumably was set up by government. The village council levied a charge on each caste community based on their ability to pay. Today the visitor is told proudly that each of the "nine castes"2 was responsible for the construction of one room in the school. During the time field work was done, efforts were begun by the sarpanch (village council chairman), to set up a veterinary clinic and seed depot in the village. 1Thakurs are Jats, a major cultivating caste in Rajasthan, Haryana, and Western Uttar Pradesh. They consider themselves to be Rajputs though they are not considered as such by other Rajputs. Bharatpur is unique in having had a Jat ruling house. 2In fact, there are more than nine, but this is a local saying. 61 Shivpura inhabitants are predominantly agriculturalists. As opposed to Hanumangarh, many more of the large landowners are self-cultivators.1 Though the Thakurs own most of the land, Ahirs and Yadavs are also impor- tant landowners. Brahmins and Baniyas are few though the latter are more important than their numbers indicate as they trade in grain and do some money-lending. Once again, the Harijans (outcastes) are landless and form the tenant and labor pool.2 There are two main Harijan castes: the Hindu Chamars (or Jatavs as they prefer to be called), and Muslim Telis.3 The artisan community is virtually non-existent: most persons go to Kumher or Bharatpur for pots and plows. Though they are a minority, there are more Muslim families here than in Hanumangarh. At the time of India's partition, thousands of Muslims were killed in Bharatpur state but none were harmed in Shivpura. Some later left for Pakistan, but during the riots village Thakurs formed vigilante committees which refused any outsider entry into the village thus protecting the Muslim population. The ones remaining range from one family of wealthy traders (Manihars by caste) to the most impoverished Teli laborers. The first thing that strikes the visitor is the marked contrast in relationships between high and low castes in the two villages. In Hanumangarh, it is rare to see Harijans and caste Hindus chatting 1This does not mean they do not lease out land. Since landholdings are large, they often retain a portion for self—cultivation and lease the rest. Jats, Ahirs, and Yadavs do not have restrictions on use of the plow, etc. 2Several have been given land grants by government of 2/5 acres each. Hence they are considered landless both by the author and them- selves. 3Muslims in India have their own castes. Telis are low in this hierarchy, and being Muslim, are considered outcastes to Hindus anyway. 62 together outside the necessary interchange required by economic linkages. In Shivpura though commensal restrictions are maintained, social rela- tionships are informal, frank and close by comparison. The sarpanch (village council chairman) has three wives, two of whom are Jat (his own caste) and the middle one is a Chamar (a Harijan) which is rare indeed. Villagers take pains to explain that the Chamar wife is not a concubine, but a properly married wife. The reasons why these differences exist are beyond the scope of this study except to point out that perhaps it is partially due to the fact that Jats dominate the village. Since they are not bound by the same strictures as are Brahmins and Baniyas, they might set a more informal tone for the rest of the community. It also points to the vast diversity one finds between villages. Though the basic crops grown in Shivpura are the same as in Hanumangarh, agricultural conditions are different. The soils are of a heavier clay-loam variety. They are capable of retaining sufficient moisture to permit farmers to divide their land and take two crops a year without irrigation. A farmer will typically sow millet on half his land in the monsoon leaving the other half fallow. On this he can plant gram, barley and mustard in the winter. The yields improve vastly with irrigation and fertilizers. Wheat is cultivated under irrigation. Mus- tard is the main cash crop and is sold in Bharatpur or Mathura for oil and oil cake (for fodder). Only one field in the village is planted to vegetables -- they are imported either from Kumher or Nadbai (eight miles away). The water table is higher than in Hanumangarh: twenty to thirty feet. It is much cheaper to sink tubewells; indeed there are several in the village. Shivpura has no electrical connections though all the 63 surrounding villages do. Thus all pump sets are diesel.1 It is rumored that electricity will reach the village by 1975. The northwest portion of village lands are irrigated by canals from the Bareta Bund -- a large artificial lake about one hundred and twenty miles to the north. The canal system is to be expanded so that in the next four to five years most of the northern area will be irrigated from it. Rainfall is more than in Hanumangarh -- 60 inches in a normal year. There is a problem of water logging and soil salinity in part of the village lands due to the high water table and flood irrigation without proper drainage. Parts of Bharatpur district are affected by monsoon floods, but not Shivpura. Farming is more mechanized than in Hanumangarh. There are at least seven privately owned tractors in Shivpura: only two in Hanumangarh proper. All land preparation and plowing operations are tractorized. The machines are increasingly used for threshing and chaff cutting as well. Produce is hauled to market by tractors. Even with the compara- tively large farms, tractor owners need to take on custom work to break even. Thus, even smaller owners can rent tractors for plowing, thresh- ing and chaff cutting operations. Schedule of Field Work and the Sample Field work was conducted between May 1972 and August 1973. The first several months were spent selecting the first village, finalizing administrative arrangements with the Governments of India and Rajasthan, and the construction and printing of the questionnaire. Interviews were 1This is an interesting point related to Shivpura's politics dis- cussed further in the study. It was the one Congress village in a Swatantra area. 64 started after the monsoon harvest and winter sowing in November 1972 and continued off and on until June 1973 with breaks for plowing and harvesting.1 The remainder of the time was spent in New Delhi for data processing. Translations of the questionnaires used are appended to this study. Within each village a sample of cultivators and laborers was ran- domly chosen for in-depth interviews lasting from one to two hours each. The field method is a combination of survey research and participant observation. All interviews were conducted personally in Hindi; the total number was 67. Had assistants been hired, the number of respon- dents would have been larger. They were not hired because it would have been difficult to get the depth and richness of information desired if highly standardized interviewing techniques were used. The respondents are similar to "informants" used by anthropologists but the author's biases in the selection of informants is controlled for by their random selection. The sample is stratified: large farmers (over ten acres), medium owners (5.1 to 10.0 acres), small farmers (1.0 to 5.0 acres), and agri- cultural tenants and laborers. The latter two categories were origi- nally to be discrete but they are not so in the real world. Most "mar- ginal" farmers (those with less than one acre of land) and the landless will lease land whenever they can and also do agricultural labor. The sizes in each stratum are not haphazard: for extension pur- poses government has a dividing line separating small from medium 1Interviewing had to be fitted to respondents' schedules. They were free in the evenings after their work in the fields. All interview- ing had to stop during the busy agricultural seasons mentioned and during "wedding seasons". See appendices for a more detailed discussion. 65 farmers at 7.5 acres and large owners are classified as owning over ten or twenty acres of land depending on the area. Marginal cultivators are below 2.5 acres. From these points adjustments were made according to the spread of land ownership in these villages. Within each stratum, the respondents represent a ten percent sample chosen randomly. Farmers' names were obtained from tehsil records. The relevant unit was not the individual title holder because of dispersed titles, but the operational cultivated unit. Thus titles had to be combined to make up the operational units with the assistance of the local patwaris. In Hanumangarh, the patwari had a reputation for being scrupulously hon- est. In Shivpura because the patwari had only recently been posted there, the assistance of a retired one was enlisted who was an original resident of the village. He knew each family and its holding. The accuracy of these men's guidance was borne out during interviews as respondents would state their full land holdings rather than the amount in their names in the tehsil records. There were very few discrepancies between what the patwaris stated, and the farmers' statements. The names of landless tenants and laborers were obtained from voters' lists. In Hanumangarh three wards contain the landless commun- ities. In Shivpura there are no distinct wards, but the patwari men- tioned was able to identify landless families directly from the rolls. The list of the landless was checked against the land records to elimi- nate any duplication. The final sample breakdown was as indicated in Table 2.4. In addition twelve more interviews were conducted with village "leaders" identified by the original respondents. They were asked in the course of interviews to identify influential persons in both a 66 TABLE 2.4 SAMPLE BREAKDOWN BY STRATA Total Number Completed Strata of Units Sample Size Interviews* Laborers/ tenants 206 21 20 Small farmers 343 34 19 Medium farmers 146 15 12 Large farmers 142 l4 l6 *Two medium farmers had bought land just prior to the inter- views bringing them into the large category. A number of small cultivators could not be contacted either because of seasonal out-migration for work in industry, or for other reasons. If a person could not be contacted after three tries, he was drOpped. See appendices for further discus- sion, and lessons learned. general and political context. The persons most frequently mentioned were interviewed using a more informal, open-ended questionnaire which is also appended. It is focused on the leaders' attitudes toward change in the two villages and perceptions of their own role in the process. It had been hoped that political competitiveness could be taken into account when the villages were selected. Two factors prevented this. First, electoral data are now available only for the whole con- stituency. This means that though a particular constituency may have three or four-way contests, any given village may turn out to be a sin- gle party area. This is impossible to determine with accuracy in advance. Second, there are in fact very few villages with more than two 67 parties seriously contesting any given election.l Splinter elements of others may be present but they tend to coalesce with the major ones for electoral purposes. Both villages happen to be two-party areas: Con- gress and Swantantra were the major contenders in each. In Shivpura, there are Socialist elements and the Jan Sangh is making small inroads. Hanumangarh also has Jan Sangh supporters. These tend to support Swatantra candidates while the Socialists throw in their support with the Congress. Mention should be made of the social and historical differences in the two villages. The data presented in the following chapters are broken down only by sample strata. Several variables were tried (includ- ing villages, caste, education, and age) but the strata showed the most significance. In view of the differences noted above, the following points should be kept in mind. First, the economic and political impacts of agrarian change are important here. Second, these effects are remark- ably uniform in both villages and the economic impacts particularly are remarkably similar to those found by other scholars (who are cited where appropriate) elsewhere in India. Third, the basic social configurations are similar (e.g., patron-client relations, caste hierarchies) though particular caste names vary. This means the specifics of the inter- action between traditional socio-political forms and the modern system are similar (see Chapter VI below). With this background in mind a discussion of the data can begin. Chapter III is focused on the spread of agricultural modernization: the extent to which new production techniques have been adopted, and the 1See R. Chandidas,_g£ al., India Votes: A Source Book on Indian Elections (New York: Humanities Press, 1968). 68 motivational and institutional constraints which prevent their wider dissemination. What is of concern is the assumption made by scholars and planners that all farmers will, given the opportunity, adopt more profitable techniques. CHAPTER III THE SPREAD OF AGRICULTURAL MODERNIZATION Going through the data it becomes clear that the specific intensive programs cannot be separated from the socio-political institutional set- ting in which they are implemented. In this chapter, land distribution is seen as the crucial variable affecting access to and adoption of new inputs. India's agricultural development strategy is predicatedcnlthe injection of new technology with the assumption that farmers, given the option, will adopt them. The point has already been made that every incentive, technical and legal, has been provided to encourage farmers to produce more. The question now arises as to how far new techniques have spread through the farming population. One needs to remember that production, however, is one part of the developmental effort: an increase in all citizens' livelihood is another. Adoption of New Inputs The initial hypothesis regarding the spread of inputs states that: the diffusion of farm inputs and access to them is a function of farm size (the larger ones having better access) which is coincident with political influence. This proposition was found to be valid with one qualification. Inputs flow to those cultivators who have bggh the power and motivation to get them. Though large farmers find it easier to obtain improved inputs, they are not all adopters. And though more 69 70 smaller farmers may wish to obtain the inputs, they cannot. The moti~ vational aspect does not negate the proposition, it adds another vari- able. Adoption of the new techniques is low compared with the potential in both villages. Though hybrids are available for a number of crops, only two are used: wheat and millet. No one in the sample has tried the new maize, barley or sorghum seeds though they grow the indigenous varieties.l Table 3.1 shows the extent of adoption in Hanumangarh and Shivpura. Aside from the overall level of adoption which is relatively low, it is striking that use of the new seeds dropped consequentially in 1972-73. Some of this is due to poor rains. It will be recalled that millet is a monsoon crop and thus is seldom irrigated. Because there was uncertainty about the rains, fewer persons were willing to use the hybrids. Additionally, some users of both the millet and wheat hybrids were not satisfied with their performance. Those who are satisfied have said they will continue to use them (see Table 3.2). The farmers who did not obtain satisfactory production levels are those who did not use the full recommended package of practices including irrigation, fertilizer and disease control. This is mainly due to a lack of infor- mation. A few respondents maintain that the hybrid varieties do not taste as good as the old ones which is a matter of taste. It should be 1In wheat it is possible to double yields with the new varieties and one can do almost as well with millet. The other three seed vari- eties still have problems with diseases, but no one had tried them any- way save for one farmer not in the sample in Hanumangarh. This might reflect the fact that maize and sorghum are not major crops, but does not explain the absence of high yielding barley seed. 71 TABLE 3.1 ADOPTION OF HYBRID SEED BY CROP AND FARM SIZE Strata Wheat Millet Used Used Never Used Used Never 1972-73 Previously Used 1972-73 Previously Used (N) Large farmers 25.0 56.2 43.8 37.5 50.0 50.0 (16) Medium farmers 41.7 41.7 58.3 25.0 58.3 41.7 (12) Small farmers 15.8 26.3 73.7 0.0 15.8 84.2 (19) Tenants 0.0 5.0 95.0 0.0 5.0 95.0 (20) Overall 17.9 29.9 70.1 13.4 28.4 71.6 (67) TABLE 3.2 INTENTION TO USE HYBRID SEED IN THE FUTURE BY FARM SIZE Yes, Yes, If Not Definitely Total Strata Definitely Help Given Sure Not Z (N) Large farmers 50.0 18.8 12.5 18.8 100.1 (16) Medium farmers 50.0 16.6 0.0 33.2 99.8 (12) Small farmers 26.0 31.6 0.0 42.1 99.7 (19) Tenants 5.0 65.0 30.0 0.0 100.0 (20) Overall 29.9 35.8 11.9 22.4 100.0 (67) 72 noted, however, that among the regular users of hybrids, farmers sow indigenous varieties for home consumption using the hybrids for sale. Table 3.2 shows the respondents' reactions when asked if they would use hybrid seeds in the future. Lack of proper information is a major hinderance to adoption as over one-third of all respondents say they will use the seeds if they learn how. Size of farm is pertinent as small farmers and tenants feel the lack of information more than do farmers in the other strata. In the category of farmers who maintain they will not take hybrids in the future, there may be some who have given up trying to get the necessary inputs and advice. Here the ques- tion of motivation (to be discussed below) may also be important. Looking at the use of chemical fertilizers, one finds a similar situation (see Table 3.3). Table 3.4 presents respondents' attitudes on the future use of fertilizers. Overall, of those wanting to use them very few make it conditional on irrigation or funds and even fewer appear to require information. Again, however, more of the smaller farmers and tenants say they will not use fertilizers. Of these most say they have tried to get them several times along with the necessary information but have not been successful. Sometimes they are told there is a shortage, but they are quick to point out that plenty of other farmers -- those with more land -- are able to get supplies. Some of the respondents are not able to utilize fertilizers because they lack irrigation. Mast of the tenants are faced with this situation. Over- all, however, the use of chemical fertilizers is higher than that of any of the improved inputs. This may be partially due to the fact that 73 TABLE 3.3 USE OF CHEMICAL FERTILIZERS BY FARM SIZE Used Used Never Strata 1972-73 Previously Used (N) Large farmers 50.0 43.8 50.0 (16) Medium farmers 41.7 50.0 50.0 (12) Small farmers 21.1 31.7 68.3 (19) Tenants 5.0 5.0 95.0 (20) Overall 26.9 29.9 70.1 (67) TABLE 3.4 INTENTION TO USE CHEMICAL FERTILIZERS IN THE FUTURE BY FARM SIZE Yes, If Not Total Strata Yes Help Given Sure No Z (N) Large farmers 56.2 6.3 0.0 37.5 100.0 (16) Medium farmers 75.0 0.0 0.0 25.0 100.0 (12) Small farmers 42.1 5.3 0.0 52.6 100.0 (19) Tenants 10.0 10.0 30.0 50.0 100.0 (20) Overall 40.3 5.8 13.6 40.3 100.0 (67) they have been promoted since the early 19603 and because the results are dramatic.1 1Because of these dramatic results, farmers often can ruin crops the first time they try chemicals by using doses far in excess of what is recommended or by not irrigating immediately after the fertilizer is applied. This does not appear to deter them perhaps because they know 74 The technique considered finally is the use of pesticides (see Table 3.5). Between a fourth and a third of all respondents have used BHC powder (benzine hexachloride) before planting to kill termites which are a major problem in both villages. Considering the extent of termite infestation and the fact that all farmers interviewed are aware of BHC's value, this is still low adoption. In Shivpura some aerial spraying of wheat and mustard has been done by government to control rust and blue beetles, and this has been mentioned by some persons. Besides BHC few farmers know specifically of any other pesticides but say they need help as they lose considerable portions of their crops to various pests and rodents.1 All respondents know there is a Plant Protection Officer at the panchayat samiti and those who have tried to contact him in both villages (save for one or two large farmers) have failed to get assistance.2 Some are worried about the effects of pesti- cides which they have heard are dangerous. These persons are reluctant that certain types of manures will do the same, particularly poultry manure which is very high in nitrogen. Mbst farmers use nitrogenous fertilizers, either CAN (calcium ammo- nium nitrate), or urea. Though the soils require phosphates, potash and trace elements, e.g., zinc, very little of these are used. A few farmers in Shivpura used super-phosphates. The reliance on nitroge- nous fertilizers, however, is raising concern in official quarters as farmers assume they will get higher yields by using them alone. In fact, the phosphates are crucial at the time the plants get their heads in order to enable the graintx>develop to its full capacity. 1This is not to say they know nothing about them: they know generic terms such as rat poisons, DDT, sprays for rust, etc., but not the Specific chemical names. 2There may be another problem here aside from the implied and often openly alleged callousness of the extension personnel. Often farmers come for help only when it is too late. Rust, for example, cannot be fully destroyed once it appears. Its appearance can be controlled, but farmers often do not seek help in time. 75 TABLE 3.5 USE OF CHEMICAL PESTICIDES BY FARM SIZE Used Used Never Strata 1972—73 Previously Used (N) Large farmers 31.3 31.3 68.7 (16) Medium farmers 41.7 41.7 58.3 (12) Small farmers 10.5 15.8 84.2 (19) Tenants 5.0 5.0 95.0 (20) Overall 19.4 20.9 79.1 (67) to try them even under guidance.1 Respondents were asked about their intention to use pesticides in the future. The results are not pre- sented as they all said they would use them if necessary. Given the current usage, this is doubtful. Since irrigation is a prerequisite for the use of the new techno- logies, can one say this is the main constraint to their adoption? On a national level it has been suggested that unless irrigation is expanded, the limits of the Green Revolution technologies have been reached. But as can be seen from Table 3.6, irrigation is not a constraint for around 50 percent of the sample. The table includes the nineteen tenants who leased in arid land only for the monsoon crop. Adoption levels are below the potential. 1There had been some tragic cases where children died from eating rat poison thinking it to be sweets of some kind. Also, malathion and parathion, used for viral and pest diseases, are sprayed and farmers are acutely conscious of the care required in the spraying operations. If inhaled, they can cause paralysis. 76 TABLE 3.6 PERCENT OF IRRIGATED LAND BY SIZE OF FARM Strata Percent of Irrigated Land Total 0 1-20 21-40 41-60 61-80 Over 80 % (N) Large farmers 6.3 18.8 46.3 6.3 3.6 18.8 100.1 (16) Medium farmers 33.3 8.3 8.3 8.3 0.0 41.5 99.7 (12) Small farmers 36.8 0.0 15.8 5.3 5.3 36.8 100.0 (19) Tenants 95.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.0 100.0 (20) Overall 46.3 5.8 16.4 4.5 3.0 23.9 99.9 (67) Relevant to this is the intensity of land use. Only 18 cultivators (26.9%) take three crops each year whereas another 16 (23.9%) can easily do so given their irrigation facilities.1 Twenty-eight farmers (41.8%) take two crOps (monsoon and winter) though around 40 (59.7%) have the capacity.2 Everyone can take a monsoon crop including tenants if they can lease land. As is clear, the land itself is not farmed as intensely 1Aside from the monsoon and winter crops, a third one may be taken in summer consisting of vegetables, fodder, and/or an additional crop of millet for either fodder or human consumption. To those who argue that irrigation by the traditional leathern bucket and oxen method is impossible in 115°F., it should be pointed out that most farmers here have electric or diesel pumps thus eliminating labor under the sun. Those taking a third cr0p irrigate in the evenings anyway for fear of scorching the plants. Power supply was not a constraint in the year field work was done. 2This includes Shivpura farmers without wells who can take two crops as some of their neighbors do, by dividing the land for the mon- soon and winter crops. See section on Shivpura, Chapter 11 above. 77 as it might be and neither are the farmers exploiting the full potential of technologies available to them. The Issue of Farmer Motivation The preceding indicates two problem areas of access and motivation. Dealing first with motivation, it is probable that if all farmers are to try to use the new inputs a short-fall in supply will result. In fact, they do not demand them even though they have both land and water. Why should this be the case? With the exception of perhaps ten percent of the sample, most farm- ers regardless of farm size follow what is a peasant strategy of farm- ing. Land is seen as a security (or collateral for credit) and a means of food production for the family -- not as a cash earner. Most fami- lies sell milk, do casual labor, or send one or two sons into government or private service for cash. Families are not self-sufficient; on the contrary they are dependent increasingly on a monetized market for basic items of daily use: cooking oil, cloth, kerosene, etc. Farming, how- ever, is not seen as a means to obtain these directly. If cash is not available through the methods mentioned respondents will obtain it from the money-lender. This can be illustrated through three examples. Landless tenants and laborers were asked if they would like some land and how much. All want land; most mention amounts between three and five acres. Why these amounts? The calculation is based on how much a man needs to feed his family and how much he can manage with family labor and two oxen. Every respondent makes the same calculation and the amounts vary according to the number of persons there are in the house. The estimates are based 78 on the availability of irrigation facilities and include the production of sufficient surplus to get credit or cash to purchase non-farm items. One respondent answered with a touch of whimsy: "How much land? Land is great wealth now; I would like lots. But five acres are enough for my family -- one should not be greedy and ask for more. That would make us as bad as the baniyas who take everything they can!" Second, when asked what credit is used for, one finds that the majority use it for non-farm purposes (see Table 3.7). TABLE 3.7 UTILIZATION OF CREDIT BY FARM SIZE Strata Use of Credit Household Farm Plus Farm Expenses, Household Inputs Debt Repayment, and Rituals Total Only Rituals* Expenses* N.A.** % (N) Large farmers 43.8 31.1 18.8 6.1 100.0 (16) Medium farmers 8.3 25.0 58.3 8.3 99.9 (12) Small farmers 47.4 36.8 10.6 5.3 100.0 (19) Tenants 45.0 0.0 40.0 15.0 100.0 (20) Overall 17.9 38.8 25.4 17.9 100.0 (67) *Includes items such as cloth, or food purchased and the rituals include mainly marriages and death feasts. **This category includes persons who either cannot get credit (see below under section on "Access and Farm Size") or who have decided to rely on their own production to meet non-farm needs. This use of credit combined with the discussion above showing that farm- ers do not fully utilize their land and irrigation resources reinforces the notion that most of them follow a "satisficing" rather than a 79 "maximizing" strategy of production. This can be illustrated by look- ing at the third example. One of the large farmers interviewed named Bachchu owns slightly over fifty acres most of which are used for grazing. Ten acres are irrigated and even these are not fully utilized. A monsoon cr0p of indigenous millet is planted on ten of the unirrigated acres. If the rains fail, so does his cr0p. In winter indigenous wheat and barley are planted (mixed) on 4.5 acres of the irrigated land. The family's main income is from milk produced by his own cows, goats and buffalos. There are between twenty and thirty animals in all. Bachchu sows no fodder though he is aware that his milk production would easily double with proper feed. When asked about inputs and advice, Bachchu maintains he can get anything he wants. This is true since he is a wealthy man and his older brother was chairman of the cooperative society at the time of the interview and a caste page; (headman) besides. Why not use high yield- ing seed then? "We don't use chemical fertilizers and so can't use the seed."1 Why not use chemical fertilizers? "We have manure from the cattle which suffices and since I am not interested in producing more grain, what is the use of investing in it?" He has ready access to the extension staff: "I know what their advice is. They tell my brother who tells me; I can find out myself anyway. But I don't take their help because I don't need to produce more. Look, we have more grain than we 1The hybrids require chemical fertilizers. If they are not used, the farmer is likely to lose his full investment. Some newer varieties give marginal returns without them, but (unless chemicals are used) a good crop of indigenous wheat will give better results. 80 can eat. We sell to the baniyas1 in the village and take more into Jaipur to sell at the magdi.2 To do this much I hardly need to sow seed in rows. Even if this weren't so, there are so many more bighas3 I can put under cultivation. As long as we get enough cash from the milk and enough to eat from the land, why bother with these other things? My brother uses some of them, but I don't see why I should." Bachchu is not an eccentric. There are Bachchu's in all strata of the sample. The issue of farmers' motivations has been dealt with extensively elsewhere. It is increasingly accepted that any actor has a number of goals in life and pecuniary profit is only one of them.4 A farmer is not only a producer, he is a father, a member of a caste, and the village community. Each of these roles imposes constraints and demands on his behavior and use of resources. They also imply that he has diverse goals to maximize. Given his range of goals, "productive" resources (both cash and time) may be channeled to non-economic ends: this is clearly illustrated in Table 3.7. 1The grain traders-cumdmoney—lenders. 2Large urban grain market. 3Indigenous land measure: Hanumangarh's local equivalent was four bighas to one acre. 4See Kusum Nair, The Lonely Furrow: Farming in the United States, Japan and India (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969); Colin Leys, "Political Perspectives," in Dudley Seers, ed., Development in a Divided World (Harmondsworth, U.K.: Penguin, 1970), pp. 106-112; Michael Lipton, "A Game Against Nature: Theories of Peasant Decision Making," The Listener (March 28, 1968), pp. 401-403 and "A Game Against Nature: Strategies of Security," The Listener (April 4, 1968), pp. 437- 39; and Barry H. Michie, "Variations in Economic Behaviour and the Green Revolution: An Anthropological Perspective," Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. VIII, #26, Review of Agriculture (June 30, 1973). 81 Besides multiple goals, however, in the Indian situation, there is no particular need for the farmer to produce anywhere near the maximum feasible as he remains economically viable without doing so. He has virtually no obligation to the state as land tax is nominal and the state has no further lien on his product. He is in a sellers' market since food is in short supply and prices rise yearly increasing his income. Almost every farmer interviewed says his income has increased over the past five years due to price rises. Some having invested in wells have increased their income from double cropping. As long as the requisite production level for economic viability is determined by sub- sistence there will be wide variations in adoption and economic perfor- mance given individual farmers' divergent goals. The higher the floor of viability the more uniform behavior will be. As regards production, it can be argued that the availability of credit from the money-lender for non-farm activities is a disincentive to increased production as the farmer need not rely on his farming to meet social obligations (except in the long run as he repays his debt). These hypotheses have ramifi- cations for the institutional parameters laid down by government to facilitate agricultural change and are discussed in the final chapter. Access and Farm Size The data collected also suggest that many farmers have limited access to the new inputs: this is the other side of the motivational coin. Where the will is present, land size becomes an important con- straint. Why this is so requires further elaboration. It has been shown that land is seen at least as a security and food provider for one's family. Beyond this, land has important social and 82 political functions everywhere. Production organization as a part of social organization reflects status and other relationships.1 In India, as in many other parts of the world, land has traditionally been con- ferred on persons as a reward for services rendered to political author- ity. In India it followed that duties performed by upper castes tended to be rewarded more: e.g., priests and soldiers (Brahmins and Rajputs) typically received the largest rewards; hence the presence of mg§§i_or 1331; holdings.2 The status enjoyed by these persons is reinforced and legitimized by the ritual hierarchy of caste. The third group whose power is coincidental with land is the bagiya_community.3 While some members traditionally enjoyed court patronage (as suppliers of provi- sions and capital) others gained local power through money-lending acti- vities over the generations. Landowners' power is also reinforced by the particular production organization in India. Where a majority of persons is dependent on agriculture for sustenance, and where the primary resource, land, is controlled by a few, the power held by those few is out of proportion to their numbers. This is clear where large tracts of land are owned by one family and cultivated by tenants. Where tenancies arose and why they did is beyond the scope of this study except to note that the pro- cess was aided by p0pulation pressures and the introduction of effective lSee Michie, gp;_cit., and also Arthur L. Stinchcomb, "Agricultural Enterprise and Rural Class Relations," in Jason Finkle and Richard Gable, eds., Political Development and Social Change (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1971), pp. 359-71. There are exceptions to this: sometimes outcaste families were given land grants too. Families like these were found in both villages. 3The traders-cumdmoney-lenders. 83 law and order enforcement which in effect bound tenants to their land- lords until debts were repaid.1 The landowners' influence also extends over the small owner-culti- vators as most large landowners are also money-lenders. Indeed, money- lending has been their dominant occupation. They may act as marketing agents, and as is discussed below, they are also major suppliers of seed, food and basic consumer items to villagers. Most activities between them and their clients are based on credit. Returning to the data, one finds that (1) villagers conceive of influence, wealth and land as coincidental, and (2) they feel their own access to resources is constrained by land size. Politically at this point it is sufficient to note that political parties normally rely on traditional elites to pull votes for them during elections.2 In return, landowners receive a number of policy payoffs and easy access to commo- dities distributed by the state. 1There are several good sources on the agrarian history of India among which are: William Moreland, The Agrarian System of Moslem India (Cambridge: W. Heffer, 1929); Walter Neale, Economic Change in Rural India (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1962); and Irfan Habib, The ,Agrarian System of Mughal India (London: Asia Publishing House, 1963). For Rajasthan see reports of the Jagirdari and Zamindari Abolition Commission, and Dhool Singh's Survey of Land Reforms in Rajasthan, op. cit. The coincidence of land and power is recognized in all studies of agrarian societies. For particular lucidity, see Doreen Warriner, Land Reform in Principle and Practice (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1969). Also see Robert Eric Frykenberg, ed., Land Control and Social Structure in Indian History (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1969). 2The bulk of literature on Indian politics deals with this. The use of large farmers and/or money-lenders as vote mobilizers is a rather cheap strategy for any party. Intuitively the same should hold true for any country where there is a similar hierarchical social order. See Paul Brass, Factional Politics in an Indian State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1965), and Myron Weiner, Party Building in a New Nation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967), pp. 467-69 where he also points out that no party is generally able to co-opt all village elites which makes for greater competition than one would assume otherwise. 84 Taking the first point, respondents were asked to name three per- sons they consider generally influential in the village. These would be persons people respect, or might turn to for solutions to everyday problems. Then about twenty minutes further into the interview in the context of discussing elections, the respondents were asked to name three persons considered to be politically important (see Table 3.8). Not all respondents could name three persons which tends to reflect the fact that they might rely on only one or two persons for advice. Fewer respondents also named politically important persons. This is primarily because of the coincidence in respondents' minds of the two kinds of influence. All respondents named persons in the large landowning class. There is a general consensus on the particular personalities chosen by all respondents with small deviations. For example, Harijans in both villages mention caste headmen (patels) who are also landowners as well as leaders from other communities. The rest of the sample of course, does not see Harijans as particularly influential for the whole village and tend to name persons from the dominant landed castes: Jats in Shivpura, and Brahmins and Baniyas in Hanumangarh. All persons men- tioned are presently or have recently been members of elected or other official bodies. The point is further illustrated in the following discussion of the respondents' perceptions of their access to inputs. Access is broken down into three categories: the receipt of sufficient inputs on time, access to credit, and access to information or advice. Since the ques- tions dealt with access on a rather general level, answers cover both governmental and private sources of each. 85 TABLE 3.8 LEADERS IDENTIFIED BY RESPONDENTS Social Attributes Non—Political Political of Leaders Leaders Leaders Respondents' Choices lst Choice 2nd Choice lst Choice 2nd Choice Caste Brahmin 28.3 13.4 8.9 13.4 Rajput 2.9 0.0 2.9 0.0 Baniya 16.4 16.4 4.5 13.4 Mina 17.9 1.5 8.9 6.0 Harijan 11.9 4.5 13.4 6.0 N.A.lDon't know 22.6 64.2 62.4 61.2 Total (%) 100 0 100 0 101.0 100.0 Occupation Landowner 8.9 8.9 0.0 0.0 Landowner-cum- money-lender 28.3 10.4 16.4 0.0 Elected landowner and money-lender 37.3 16.4 21.2 16.4 Laborer 2.9 0.0 0.0 14.9 N.A.lDon't know 22.6 64.2 62.4 68.7 Total (%) 100.0 99.9 100.0 100.0 Party Affiliation Congress 56.5 27.9 28.4 32.9 Swatantra 20.9 8.9 7.8 5.9 Don't know 22.6 64.2 62.4 61.2 Total (%) 100.0 101.0 98.6 100 0 The first dimension deals with the availability of inputs on time (see Table 3.9). Most farmers claim they have difficulty most of the time. Almost all the large farmers can get timely supplies whereas around 75 percent of all others cannot. Of the small farmers and tenants, those who say they have no problems, are persons who save seed at home 86 TABLE 3.9 WHETHER RESPONDENTS HAVE DIFFICULTY GETTING INPUTS ON TIME BY FARM SIZE Strata Whether Inputs are Available on Time Normally Often Has Never Gets Total on Time Problems on Time N.A.* % (N) Large farmers 56.3 31.2 12.5 0.0 100.0 (16) Medium farmers 33.3 25.1 41.6 0.0 100.0 (12) Small farmers 42.1 10.5 31.6 15.8 100.0 (19) Tenants/Laborers 30.0 30.0 10.0 30.0 100.0 (20) Overall 40.3 28.3 22.4 9.0' 100.0 (67) *Includes persons who either save seed at home from previous season or who were unable to lease land during 1972-73. from the previous crop because they know they are unable to buy any at planting time. Few of these use any additional inputs such as ferti- lizers. When asked what the problem is, they reply they lack money, credit, and influence with the distributors. "Big people help their own ‘ kind -- who looks to us. Even if we are farming some big farmers' lands, do they see to it that we have seed and water? No, we not only pay rent for the land but also for all the inputs as well." Related to this is the question, "If you are not getting these things, who in your Opinion is getting them?" (see Table 3.10). Most mention persons who have plenty of land, influence and money -- the three again being seen as coincident. "Big people, those with large amounts of land. They have money and know officers at the Samiti or in 87 TABLE 3.10 WHO RESPONDENTS FEEL GET THE INPUTS READILY Strata Types of Persons Getting Inputs Big, Anyone No One Gov't. Influential With Due to D.K. Total Servants (Farmers .. Money Scarcity N.A. % (N) Large farmers 6.3 31.3 56.2 6.3 0.0 100.1 (16) Medium farmers 0.0 58.3 8.3 0.0 33.3 99.9 (12) Small farmers 5.2 26.3 26.3 0.0 42.2 100.0 (19) Tenants/ Laborers 0.0 15.0 25.0 0.0 60.0 100.0 (20) Overall 3.0 29.9 29.9 1.5 35.8 100.1 (67) Jaipur and they are listened to."1 "If a small man even tries to go to the Samiti, he may get to see some clerk, but never anyone who can help him. We are always told the BDO (Block Development Officer) is busy -- but busy with what? Drinking tea with the big men." One or two farmers mention general scarcity as a problem. These are men from Shivpura who tried unsuccessfully to get hybrid seeds that year. One man said he did not know what the problem was but he could not find supplies most of the time. The rest of the sample feels supplies are plentiful and anyone with ready cash can buy them. Sometimes the Samiti officers sell them on the black market, but they are available for those who try. 1The Hindi term used translates as "big men" and has the connota- tion of wealthy and influential. 88 Next turning to farmers and tenants' access to credit, it is clear the same constraint of land size is operative (see Table 3.11). The major channels through which it is available are outlined in Chapter I. TABLE 3.11 AVAILABILITY OF CREDIT BY SIZE OF FARM Strata Whether Respondents Get Enough Credit Total Yes Sometimes Never No Need % (N) Large farmers 81.2 18.8 0.0 0.0 100.0 (16) Medium farmers 16.7 41.7 41.7 0.0 100.1 (12) Small farmers 15.8 36.8 36.8 10.6 100.0 (19) Tenants/Laborers 10.0 5.0 75.0 10.0 100.0 (20) Overall 29.8 40.3 23.9 5.9 99.9 (67) Most farmers have trouble obtaining credit either all or most of the time. It is interesting that persons who feel no need for credit are small farmers and tenants-cumelaborers. Two small owners have made a conscious break from the cultivators' cycle of perpetual indebtedness. They now rely on their land for both food and additional cash require- ments.1 As far as the tenants are concerned, they are unable to obtain credit without land for collateral. Each year they try to lease any amount of land for the monsoon season and buy seed from whatever little 1Both might take loans for major expenses such as marriages, but rely on their own production for household and farm expenses. One con- tributed Rs. 200/- ($26.66) to the construction of a new physics lab at the High School though he had studied only through the fifth class him- self. Both view farming as a business. 89 they can save from their earnings as casual or agricultural laborers. Both maintain they cannot afford to lease in land for a full year because of their lack of capital. Credit is a constraint to a point for small farmers as well as tenants and laborers. As land size falls, so money-lenders' interest rates rise. Official credit is available onlytxnthose who own 2.5 acres or more. Therefore, for around half of the sample in the small farmers' category, credit is more expensive than it is for any other class of cultivators. As regards the tenants and laborers, most of them cannot obtain any from the regular private sources because of their lack of collateral.1 A few have long-standing ties with particular money-lend- ing families whose tenants they might have been over several genera- tions. These are able to get loans and repay them through labor and/or cropsharing. While such arrangements mean access to credit, they also make it impossible to repay fully one's debt. Loans from money-lenders whether taken in cash or kind are nor- mally repaid in kind. Though lenders maintain they are willing to accept payment in cash, their advantage lies in grain since the grain trade is their main income earner. The loan's value is set in kind when it is taken, based on grain prices at the previous harvest. Should a farmer take a loan for his winter crop, he will repay x quintals of wheat or barley at whatever the money-lender chooses to estimate the price will be that year based on the last. Smaller cultivators in particular find the bulk of their crop has been mortgaged before it is sown. The money- lender obtains grain cheaply holding onto it until the market prices rise 1There are special loans available to Harijans for housing construc- tion and other purposes which are discussed below in Chapter IV. 90 later in the season. Many cultivators find themselves short of food stocks by the middle or end of the cropping season and have to buy back their own produce at inflated rates. Even worse, they often obtain these additional stocks on loan thus adding interest also at inflated rates. It will be recalled that interest rates charged by money-lenders range from 12 to 50 percent pg: appgm. Why do cultivators not utilize official channels where interest is much lower? Some persons do of course, and do so mainly for the pur- chase of pump sets or other farm machinery (see Table 3.12). Official credit is still vastly under-utilized. TABLE 3.12 SOURCES OF CREDIT USED BY FARM SIZE* Strata Credit Sources Money Friends, State or Panchayat Coop- Lender Relatives Land Bank Samiti** erative (N) Large farmers 81.3 31.3 0.0 0.0 37.5 (16) Medium farmers 83.3 50.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 (12) Small farmers 84.2 15.7 5.3 5.3 10.5 (19) Tenants/Laborers 60.0 20.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 (20) Overall 76.0 26.9 1.5 1.5 11.9 (67) *Totals are not 100.0% as respondents could give more than one response. **Only one person had an outstanding loan from this source. The samitis no longer extend credit. 1Rates vary in the two villages: in Hanumangarh they range from 12 to 24 percent and in Shivpura from 25 to 50 percent. If loans are taken in kind (grain or seed) interest is double that charged for cash and may even be compounded during the year. 91 Three main reasons are given for not using official credit. The most frequent response is that there is too much red tape involved with government loans. This is true from the cultivator's perspective. He is required for example, to show he has no outstanding debt at any other governmental agency. He needs proof of the requisite amount of land ownership. Official estimates might be asked for unless loans are given in kind (e.g., seed) which have to be submitted by officials at the panchayat samiti or district offices. Technical appraisals might be asked for in some situations: if a farmer wants to install a pump set, he needs an estimate from irrigation engineers to show the well has sufficient water for proper utilization of the pump set. While these procedures have a rationale, they tend to intimidate or baffle some farmers. Second, several farmers state frankly that government requires pay- ment on time while the money-lender does not. They are afraid their land might be auctioned off by government if they default. This has never actually happened in anyone's memory.1 On the contrary, several laborers and smaller cultivators' families have lost land through money- lenders' foreclosures. Money-lenders tend to reinforce farmers' fears of governmental action and in at least one case had threatened to lLong, complex legal provisions make it difficult for government to foreclose. The same is true for money-lenders, but since their debtors are either unable financially or unwilling to deal in court, informal arrangements often mean the cultivator loses d3 facto control of his land until such time as the debt is repaid which is almost impossible without use of the land. Government on the other hand, aside from the legalities of notices and foreclosure, must grant debt relief in times of natural disasters which occur with alarming regularity. The recuperation of public loans is abysmally low in India. Farmers have been known to take governments loans to repay money-lenders. Such incidents led government to stOp all "taccavi" or general purpose cash loans. 92 withdraw credit from a farmer if he took a loan from the land mortgage bank. To an extent private credit is more flexible in that debts can continue for long periods of time as long as the bulk of the interest is paid each year. Its ready availability, however, means that farmers do not need to rely primarily on their farming to meet expenses. This lowers the floor of production required to remain viable in agriculture and as such, detracts from the potential productivity of farmers. The crux of the matter is that money-lenders provide "untied" cre- dit usable for any purpose without accounting. As mentioned official credit is tied, and for most purposes the cultivator never receives any cash in hand. Loans are only for farm or other productive enterprises. Subsistence cultivators seldom separate farm and household budgets but by the respondents' own reckoning, most of their credit is used for non- farm purposes (as is apparent in Table 3.7 above). A sizable proportion is used for ritual and social obligations, e.g., marriages and death feasts. The third dimension of access discussed is the availability of advice or information. When asked if they farm according to advice given by extension agents, only 15 percent of all respondents say they try. Most say they do not even try to find out what extension agents advise since the agents have no interest in the small farmers anyway (see Table 3.13). Many of these respondents have tried unsuccessfully in the past to approach either the village level worker or another member of the samiti staff. Of the 15 percent who try to farm according to extension agents' advice, most are in the large stratum. Of course, there are persons in 93 TABLE 3.13 WHETHER RESPONDENTS USE EXTENSION ADVICE BY LAND SIZE Strata Whether Respondents Use Extension Advice Doesn't Know What Total Yes No .,Agents Say % (N) Large farmers 30.0 25.0 45.0 100.0 (16) Medium farmers 16.7 16.7 66.7 100.1 (12) Small farmers 10.6 5.3 84.2 100.1 (19) Tenants/Laborers 5.0 95.0 0.0 100.0 (20) Overall 14.9 38.8 46.3 100.0 (67) each stratum like Bachchu who have no interest in improving their pro- duction, and hence make no attempt to contact extension workers. Of the 70 percent or so who do not get advice, most of the medium and especially the smaller cultivators feel their land is the major hindrance. One of the small farmers puts it this way: The government wants more food produced, but they feel only big farmers can do this. The big farmers too never tell Samiti people to come help us though they have the influence to make them do their jobs. This may be because the big farmers too are not interested or don't want us to progress. Why? I don't know. Maybe because then we would not be under their influence. As it is now many small farmers can't save seed enough even though they try to from the previous year's crap. They need it for food and then they are dependent on the big farmer who has a surplus and who is a money-lender as well. But you know, a small man has to work harder than the big one because his small farm is all he has to live on. So why is it that government won't help us? Tell me that! Of course, there are lazy small farmers too -— but on the whole they work harder... 94 Tenants almost laugh when asked about farming on the advice of the extension staff. Most of them say there is no way they can benefit from the advice even if they get it. "We have no land. What we can lease is the worst land possible because landowners keep the best for them- selves. What will we do with advice whatever it is?" "We know what they say, but why should we follow it with no land of our own? Only the next tenant or the landlord himself will profit from it. If landlords and government want higher yields, let them pay for them." Other comments however reflect another side. "They (the extension agents) won't come to us, nor will they see us if we go there. We have no land. They aren't interested in the small man anyway. Farming has become a business for big people only." "We don't know anyone there (the samiti) and you have to have influence to get these things. Only big farmers have influence. Even the small landowners cannot get any- thing. And we hear they ask for money. What can we do?" "They don't listen to small men anyway -- do you think they would listen to Harijans?"l One tenant said she tried to farm according to the extension agent's recommendations. Her husband is a pump mechanic at the city water works. He is also fairly influential among a segment of the Raiger (leatherworkers') caste. This family has leased land from the same Brahmin family for two generations. The landlord provides only irrigation facilities and those too have been cut off since he defaulted on the payment of electrical bills for the pump set. Until this hap- pened, the tenants used both high yielding wheat and millet seed: they are the only tenants in the sample who did so. 1 Outcastes. 95 Land presents two constraints for tenants. One is motivational in that they are not prepared to invest in what is not theirs and from which they gain only temporary advantage. Some observers have made the point that landownership may not be the crucial variable. What is necessary is security of tenure.1 The comments cited above clearly reflect insecurity of tenure and this is discussed at length in Chapter IV. Myths and Realities of Small Farm Productivity The second constraint is that neither the extension agents nor the large landowners are interested in tenants' productivity. Landowners who are serious about increasing production by and large do their own farming or supervise their tenants closely, providing proper seed and other inputs. Tractors make it possible for them to dispense with tenants altogether and hire farm managers. Most however do not invest much in their farms; they get food enough for their families as it is, plus a moderate surplus. Their money—lending and grain trading activi- ties are more important. Interviews conducted with village leaders support the perceptions of small farmers and tenants. The large farmer's desire to control agricultural resources coincides with his belief that small farms cannot produce a surplus. These beliefs further coincide with those of admini- strators in charge of program implementation who see it as a waste of time to cajole small farmers into adopting new practices. A11 leaders feel that agricultural production has increased conse- quentially with the intensive programs. Some mention that increased lSee Doreen warriner, op. cit., and the Ford Foundation Report cited above, Chapter I. 96 irrigation has caused the most change by permitting double cropping. Which groups have benefitted the most from the programs? "Mainly peo- ple like myself who have lots of land because we can demand the inputs. The small farmers are in trouble: they neither demand them nor can they really produce much more.‘ (the village headman of Shivpura) "The bigger farmers, of course, and they don't really need the government's help except perhaps for extension advice. It is the smaller man who needs the subsidies and loans —- but he is so far denied access to them and it is the fault of government that thinks there is no use putting so much into the small farmer -- though let me tell you he has to work harder than the big one." (retired patwari, Shivpura) "People who try -- both big and small farmers though the big farmers have much more advantage. They can afford the inputs and also the samiti will give to them first assuming they will have a higher increase in production." (caste headman in Hanumangarh, big farmer and member of the Congress Party). One large farmer sums it up this way: "How can government expect the small man to make up food deficits? These people have only four or five bighas or land and can barely keep themselves alive. Everyone says they work very hard, but that is not true. It is the man who has at least twenty acres who can produce a surplus. We work hard but govern- ment always talks of the small man. When we are the ones who produce for market, why should government give land to Harijans or start pro- grams for small farmers? Are these the real farmers of India?" Finally, from conversations with extension personnel it becomes clear that while provisions are made for assisting small cultivators, few peo- ple feel these are serious attempts to raise their productivity. With a 97 national food shortage, the effort is aimed at extracting surpluses from larger landowners for urban markets. Schemes to give small culti- vators credit or other inputs are viewed as subsidy measures to prevent destitution and enable survival, not as a part of increasing overall productivity.l As was pointed out in Chapter I, the idea is to raise production by investing scarce resources into those sectors of agri- culture which are assumed to respond the fastest. The assumption that large farmers gill produce more per unit of land is not a valid one. Increasing numbers of studies show it is the smaller cultivator who outproduces the larger given similar irrigation resources. Aside from studies done by others, the following points are clear here though farmers were not asked for precise production figures.2 (Also see.Figure 3.1 for a cross national comparison of farm producti- vity by farm size.) As with Bachchu, the lands of most of the larger farmers are vastly under-utilized. Some cite irrigation as a constraint, but few fully exploit such irrigation as they have. Bachchu for example, uses only 4.5 of his irrigated ten acres. Nor do any invest in more than one well and pump set though they have both the personal resources and credit access to do so. Even farmers like Bachchu who rely on animal hus- bandry rather than grain for income do not fully use their land. Milk production is abysmally low because of a lack of proper feed. A Peace Corps Volunteer in the area working in dairy development started a fodder 1Drawn from discussion with state, district and samiti level per- sonnel. See also the Ford Foundation report, op. cit. 2Also see G. R. Saini, "Farm Size, Productivity and Returns to Scale," Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. IV, #26 (1969), and Wilfred Malenbaum, Modern India's Economy (Columbus, Ohio: Charles E. Merrill, 1971), pp. 148-51. 98 FIGURE 3.1 OUTPUT PER HECTARE FOR FARM SIZE GROUPS Relative Output 30 India Brazil Brazil Columbia Columbia Mexico (For each Country, bar at left represents output per hectare for small— est farm size group. Bars to the right represent successively larger farms with their output per hectare expressed as a percent of that of the smallest size group.) SOURCE: Peter Dorner and Don Kanel, "The Economic Case for Land Reform," paper presented at the Agency for International Development Spring Review on Land Reform, Washington, D. C., June 1970. (Mimeo- graphed.) 99 1(India) Erven J. Long, "The Economic Basis of Land Reform in Underdeveloped Economies," Land Economics (May 1961), pp. 113-23. The paper uses data for the mid- and late 19503 gathered by the Studies in Economics of Farm Management, Ministry of Food and Agriculture, Govern- ment of India, New Delhi. Output as gross value in rupees per acre. Long classified actual farm sizes into four size groups -- smallest, second smallest, second largest, largest -- for each of eight areas in seven states, and presented output per size group as the average of the eight areas. (Data from more than 1,000 farms from seven states.) 2(Brazil) Roger G. Johnson and Reuben C. Buse, A Study of Farm Size and Economic Performance in Old Santa Rosa, Rio Grande do Sul, Land Tenure Center Research Paper No. 27 (Madison: University of Wis- consin, August 1967), pp. 40-61. Output as net sales per productive hectare, in thousands of cruzeiros (1963). Actual farm sizes included in each size class are: (l) 0 - 10 hectares; (2) 10.1 — 20 hectares; (3) 20.1 - 40 hectares; (4) 40.1 - 100 hectares; and (5) more than 100 hectares. (Sample of 311 farms.) 3(Brazil, 1950) Solon L. Barraclough and Arthur L. Domike, "Agra- rian Structure in Seven Latin American Countries," Land Economics (November 1966), pp. 391—424. Also issued as Land Tenure Center Reprint No. 25 (Madison: University of Wisconsin, 1966). Output as percent of value of sub-family (smallest) farm production per cultivated hectare. The authors classed actual farm sizes into four groups: sub-family, family, multi-family medium, and multi-family large. (Based on National Census data.) 4(Colombia, 1960) Ibid., using same measures of output and same farm size criteria. (Based on National Census data.) 5(Colombia, 1966) Emil Haney, "The Economic Reorganization of Minifundia in a Highland Community of Colombia," Ph.D. thesis in pro- gress, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin. Output as gross value per hectare, in U. S. dollars. Actual farm sizes included in each size class are: (1) less than one hectare; (2) l — 2.99 hectares; (3) 3 - 9.99 hectares; and (4) more than ten hectares. (Sample of 203 farms in a highland community of Colombia.) 6(Mexico, 1960) Folke Dovring, "Land Reform and Productivity: The Mexican Case, A Preliminary Analysis," AERR-83, Department of Agricul- tural Economics, Agricultural Experiment Station, University of Illinois, November 1966, 17 pages. Also issued as Land Tenure Center Paper No. 63 (Madison: University of Wisconsin, January 1969), pp. 2-10. Output as gross value per hectare of arable land, in pesos. Actual farm sizes included in each size class are: (1) less than five hectares in the private sector (average about 1.45 hectares); (2) ejido lands averaging about seven hectares per ejido member (only about two percent of 1.6 million ejido members engage in collective farming); and (3) more than five hectares in the private sector (average about 27 hectares). (Based on National Census data.) 100 production scheme. Of the thirty or so farmers who took lucerne seed the first year, all but two or three would fall into the small farmer stratum of this study. One would assume they have less land to divert for such a crop. More small cultivators take more crops each year than the larger farmers.l Also more of the former try to find out about the hybrid seeds. Some obtained small amounts in previous years from neighbors and grew them with disastrous results. Often the seed is impure or genetic breakdown has started.2 They grow them like indigenous varie- ties not knowing that chemical fertilizers are required, that seed has to be planted shallowly, and that these varieties are prone to diseases which do not affect native strains. One farmer interviewed owned only 1.5 acres of land. He proudly displayed his half acre of Kalyan Sona wheat during the interview.3 He was trying it for the first time having got the seed from a friend. When asked how much fertilizer he had used, he replied he had used only a little manure from his animals. The wheat was just beginning to tiller and we recommended that he immediately get some urea and super- phosphates or else he would not even get back the cost of his seed. 1This controls for irrigation; a comparison of farmers with simi- lar facilities. 2Seed often gets mixed with indigenous types over time. Also since the genetic structure is not very stable, farmers should purchase new stock about every three years or the yields decline. Wheat seed appears to be more stable than maize or other coarse grains, but even there seed stock must be replaced. 3One of the wheat hybrids; a white variety developed from the original Mexican imports. 101 Even with ready cash he was unable to obtain enough of these.1 "But everyone says these seeds produce more than twice that of dg§i_wheat." "Yes, but not unless you put all these other things on. Didn't anyone tell you?" "No." Narayan's wheat problem was finally solved by an onslaught of aphids for which not even this research team could move the Samiti fora sprayer and pesticides though we were informed the aphids would present a problem for all the surrounding fields. The tale was all too common. Most Sprayers were not functioning; those that were in order were being used by the chairman of the samiti and some of his friends. As a rule, smaller farmers market a higher proportion of their pro- duce than do the large ones. The data here are imprecise but suggest that small cultivators market between 40 and 50 percent of each crop whereas large ones sell only around 25 percent. This is taken from farmers' own estimates for each crop grown and controls for cash crops like mustard in Shivpura, of which everyone sells 100 percent. This may be so for a number of reasons. Smaller farmers being more in debt may have to pay out more at harvest. Or it may be that because they are constrained by a lack of credit for everyday items of consumption, they have to rely on themselves to earn the required amount of cash. Both may be true to a point, but they suggest that small plots exercise a constraint that makes farmers use the land more intensively and part with 1In fact, the cooperative had several quintals of each left in its store house at the end of the cropping season. The cooperative secre- tary said there simply was not enough demand for them. Not only Narayan, but a number of other farmers had been told that supplies were finished. 102 a larger share of their produce. This fact is also borne out for other countries such as Mexico.1 Finally, a number of the entrepreneurial large farmers who take their farming seriously contend there is a size constraint on effi- ciency if one is to use the new varieties. The headman of Shivpura puts only a fourth of his sixty irrigated acres under high yielding wheat. As he points out, the high yields promised by government are only pos- sible on relatively small plots because of the intensity of cultivation required. The weeding and irrigation operations in particular require the kind of care which is impossible to exercise on large farms. Summary In summarizing the findings of this chapter, it can be seen that the spread of new technologies is not very wide in these two villages. There are two constraints to their adoption. One is the motivation of farmers and this is linked to their perception of farming as a subsis- tence, rather than a commercial enterprise. The second is the con- straint of land size. Even when farmers desire new inputs, they are unable to obtain them if they are in the smaller land ownership cate- gories. Second, the constraint of land size is perceived by cultivators, village leaders, and governmental personnel. Smaller farmers see this as a result of the coincidence of land ownership, wealth and political influence. The latter two groups (leaders and government personnel) lSee Folke Dovring, "Land Reform in Mexico," paper presented at the Agency for International Development Spring Review of Land Reform, Washington, D. C., June 1970, p. 20. (Mimeographed.) 103 essentially see it as a waste of time and resources to invest in the small or medium cultivator. Third, on a general level, it appears to be the smaller culti- vator who is more interested in new inputs. He also tends to make fuller use of his resources than does the large cultivator though both use less than the maximum amount. Fourth, these findings raise questions about three basic assump- tions of India's approach to agricultural modernization. First, one is led to question the assumption that all farmers will typically respond to more profitable or productive means of production. Second, one has to question the assumption that those who already have more resources to begin with are likely to respond the fastest to new incentives. Third, it appears that adoption patterns may require constraints as well as incentives, which eliminate the less productive patterns of behavior. Particularly noteworthy in this regard is farmers' reliance on expensive but loose credit available from money-lenders to meet household and social obligations. The alternative, more productive behavior of course, would be to channel this credit into farming and to meet non-farm expenses from increased profits. Finally, even with this evidence, it would seem more rational to divert resources and attention to smaller cultivators who (I) feel the need to depend on their own production and (2) who constitute a far larger base of political support for any political party that chooses to do so. CHAPTER IV CHANGES IN SECURITY 0F TENURE AND EMPLOYMENT Agricultural modernization does more than raise farm productivity. The effects of new technology on rural organization were discussed in Chapter I. Here one can see the extent to which rural organization has altered: the emphasis in this chapter is on changes in economic rela- tionships as they form the basis of interdependencies:havillage society. One finds the first impact of change is felt by the landless: tenants and laborers alike. There is concern in official quarters about rising unemployment levels in India. Some of this is due to normal rises in population. Controlling for that however, the concern exists that ten- ants and laborers displaced from agriculture migrate into urban areas swelling the ranks of the urban unemployed. The debate continues as to whether the "Green Revolution" is responsible for higher unemployment rates or if more employment is possible through the use of the new tech- nologies. Institutional Changgs: Technology and Legal Framework It has already been stated that over time, the goals of production have superceded those of equality. This is borne out in the following analysis of the institutional parameters dealing with security of tenure. The data presented show how these parameters in fact constrain tenant security leaving landowners a free hand to develop their resources. 104 105 These data also suggest that the new "package" of technologies accele- rates obsolescence of tenants and labor. Unemployment is worse in areas other than Rajasthan where pressure on land is greater and large-scale mechanization has gone further. Desperation has erupted into political violence: some organized, some anomic. The best-known of violent uprisings in recent years is the Naxalbari Movement linked with the Community Party of India (Marxist- Leninist).1 In this and some other incidents, landless labor and/or tenants have forcibly evicted landowners, harvested crops, and retained the land. There have been murders committed on both sides with govern- ment primarily aiding the landowners. A major point here is that farming is highly profitable in India. A rough calculation based on discussions with farmers in both villages indicates net profits between 40 and 60 percent depending on how well the farmer cultivates: whether he irrigates on time, uses sufficient manure, weeds thoroughly, etc. Even using all recommended inputs to obtain optimal yields (including hybrid seeds) the costs per acre are at most Rs. 700.00 ($93.33). With a yield of 27 to 28 quintals per acre, and a selling price of Rs. 110.00 ($14.66) per quintal of wheat on the Open market, the net profit is Rs. 1,913.00 ($255.06) per acre.2 These 1The movement gets its name from the Naxalbari region of Bengal state where it began. Starting by organizing tea plantation labor, party workers then moved into other agricultural areas. To the author's mind, its mistake was to include university students and other urban elements which made it easier for government to suppress it and this also destroyed the dynamic of rural ideology and participation. The party mentioned is the most "left" and "Peking" oriented of India's four communist parties. It does not contest elections. See Paul R. Brass and Marcus F. Franda, eds., Radical Politics in South Asia (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1973), passim. 2Calculations are based on input recommendations from Government of Rajasthan, Ministry of Agriculture found in the Rajasthan Farm Diary for 106 calculations do not include allowances for depreciation and replacement of capital investments.1 The reader will recall that producers have virtually no financial obligation to the state or any other external body and thus are under no constraint to produce the maximum feasible. Given these profits, entrepreneurial farmers have developed their farms well and are reluctant to share gains with tenants and labor. Tractors make it unnecessary to share as much. They also have status value. Where irrigation has been extended or improved permitting double or triple cropping, the annual labor requirement has obviously risen. There are more harvest and weeding times. Because the biochemical inputs of the Green Revolution require more intensive cultivation, the labor input of each cr0p has increased somewhat. Looking to these factors, some economists hold thattfluzGreen Revolution has increased employment.2 extension workers, 1972, and prices of inputs provided by the Panchayat Samiti officers of Hanumangarh and Kumher, Rajasthan. The selling price is that of wheat on the free market in Hanumangarh after harvest, 1973. The costs of pesticides requirements are estimated because some crops may be afflicted with more diseases than others: to the author's mind a generous amount has been added for these. 1Another basis of calculation was provided by the Block Develop— ment Officer for Shivpura. This assumes the cultivator uses a tractor on hire, is using Kalyan Sona seed and all recommended practices. It does not include depreciation or replacement for capital improvements. Costs: Plowing Rs. 80/- Levelling Rs. 15/- Sowing Rs. 25/- Seed Rs. 80/- Manure (organic) Rs. 40/— Chemical fertilizer Rs. 140/- Pesticides Rs. 25/- Irrigation Rs. 125/- Weeding Rs. 15/- Harvesting Rs. 35/- Threshing and winnowing Rs. 70/- Total cost per acre Rs. 650/- ($86.66) 2 Reams have been written on increased man-hours, man-days, etc. and the Green Revolution. Such precise calculations omit predictions of 107 The counter argument is that while this may be so, the biochemical components are divisible and "neutral to scale". It is the concomitant increase in the rate and scale of farm mechanization that raises unemployment. This argument needs elaboration before looking at changes in the two villages. Since farming is profitable and the income earned is not taxed, it has attracted both land speculators and entrepreneurs. Land values have risen rapidly making it difficult for persons of moderate means to buy any. The levels of investment the newcomers are willing and able to make will raise the scale of farming. The two scales (the small subsis- tence peasant vs. the entrepreneurial, commercial farmer) can coexist only as long as there are food shortages. Once these are overcome (which is within the realm of technical feasibility) the competition of scales will force out the smaller farmer.1 Additionally, security of tenure is affected by the institutional framework. The legal provisions regulating rates and conditions of tenancies enacted to safeguard tenants' interests have worked against them. It will be recalled that by 1957-58, most jagirs and zamindari intermediary rights had been abolished. Certain portions of land could be retained by intermediaries for self-cultivation. Tenants are, continued mechanization and as such obfuscate the real issue: the rise in the scale of farming required to remain viable over the longer— term. 1See V. M. Rao, "Village Lease Markets for Agricultural Land," Economic and Political Weekly, op, cit. where he forecasts the creation of a class of petty land leasors who cannot afford to cultivate them- selves and rent their farms to larger farmers. 108 however, still employed to cultivate these resumed lands as they are also employed on former mgafi or rzotwari holdings.1 The goals of tenancy reform are (l) to protect tenants from econo- mic exploitation by the landlords, (2) to provide a livelihood and security of tenure for them, and (3) to provide ownership where feasible to the tenants. Three bodies of legislation have been enacted to deal with each of these. First, in the area of rent regulation, rents cannot exceed one- sixth of the gross product (per tenant) in Rajasthan. In the field no tenant interviewed paid less than one-fourth. The second area of legis- lation aims at security of tenure: though a landowner has the right to self-cultivate a certain amount of land, some minimum amount of each tenant's holding must be left to him. Further, the tenant cannot be evicted from his holding except for nonpayment of rent or some other grave offense. The final area of legislation provides for the transfer of landownership to the tenant: on non-resumable land, tenants may claim ownership if they have farmed the same plot/s for three consecu- tive years. It is impossible to enforce this body of legislation. It does not cover most tenants as it includes only those registered as such (see 1All land holdings regardless of their previous classifications (e.g., muafi or ryotwari) are now called khatedari holdings: translated as "state's tenants". Thus the tenants referred to in this context are what would have the legal classification of sub-tenants, and under these legal provisions should be registered as such in the land records. 2Data are from the Indian Council of Agricultural Research, Hand- book of Agriculture (New Delhi: Indian Council of Agricultural Research, 1969), pp. 722-25. See also Implementation of Land Reforms, A Review by the Land Reforms Implementation Committee of the National Development Council (New Delhi: Planning Commission, August 1966), pp. 122-26. 109 above). Second, since land is at a premium.tenants are in no position to insist on legal rental rates as there are many waiting in line for land who are willing to pay twice or three times that amount. The pro- visions regarding ownership too are not enforceable as they assume —- incorrectly - that the state knows which persons are tenants to whom and the plots cultivated by them. Knowing the limits and loopholes of the legislation, landlords rotate tenants each year so that none has a right to claim help under any provisions for security or ownership. It was pointed out in Chapter II that most leases are hereditary but oral. With the new laws land- owners no longer maintain the hereditary tenurial system. They have also made sure that oral leases are unacceptable in court by changing tenants and their plots every year. Only in exceptional cases have ten— ants kept the same plots year after year: where a degree of trust or perhaps the coercion of high indebtedness exists between landlord and tenant. Finally, there are few tenants who can afford to take landowners to court. Legal costs are high especially in view of the fact that civil cases may be tied up in court for years.1 Even if a tenant could afford to go to court, the pressure from landowners on him and his family would be difficult to bear. In the intervening time he would not be able to lease in any land, and if he lost in court, he would probably never again be able to get employment in the village. 1A farmer interviewed by Barry H. Michie fought his claim for twenty years before it was settled in his favor. Three months later he had still not received d3 facto ownership as its illegal occupant refused to vacate it. 110 Several implications can be drawn from this discussion, some of which are discussed further in this chapter. Here it is sufficient to point out two points. First, one has to assume that government sees tenancy legislation as providing some kind of symbolic reassurance to the landless since, in fact, no strong attempt has been made to enforce it. Second, it is probable that the nonenforcement is due to two rea- sons: (1) administrative incapacity,1 and (2) a fear that enforcement will jeopardize the security of owner-cultivators who are considered important for food production. The latter point follows the logic of the Ford Foundation Report which cautioned against land reforms which might affect "farms that are efficiently and productively operated."2 Landowners' attitudes toward the landless can be seen in the follow- ing incident which occurred in Hanumangarh several years ago.3 Govern- ment has a scheme through which Scheduled Castes and Tribes are eligible for land allotments. The plots come from land resumed by the state from jagirs or other ceiling legislation. Land classified as "cultivable wastes" is also available for distribution. Much of this is arid and eroded but can be used for farming with proper investments. 1Primarily a lack of sufficient personnel and detailed land records. 2India's Food Crisis and Steps to Meet It, Op. cit., p. 29. See above in Chapter I for the full discussion. 3I first heard about this approximately three months after arriving in the village. Every respondent in the tenant/labor category verified it and several owner-cultivators also recited the same tale showing how they refused to let the scarce amount of land available go to persons who are not "real farmers." 4The required investments are very high: as much as Rs. 30,000 to 40,000 ($4,000.00 to $5,333.00) depending on the extent of erosion and depth of ground water. Estimates are from samiti personnel and the patwari of Hanumangarh. 111 Traditionally much of it was used for grazing and some for monsoon crops by all villagers. A number of allotments of 3.13 acres per household were made a few years back. The recipients all Harijans, made ready to start cultiva- tion. Caste Hindus however, made it clear they would not permit Hari- jans to use the plots though there remained abundant land for grazing. The Harijans, to test their ownership rights, went out in a group to begin plowing. They were met by groups of stave-wielding farmers who literally beat them back. The Harijans reported the incident to the police and asked for protection which was promised. No action followed however, and the police finally told the allottees to choose between themselves and the caste Hindus. Several Harijans interviewed felt the villagers must have "paid off" the police -- otherwise why would they not help? Others felt it portrayed the feeling upper castes have about the legitimacy of Harijans' claim to land at all as it is a scarce commodity. When field work was conducted none of the allottees could farm their plots though the land was recorded in their names and they paid the land tax on it.1 Tenancies With this background the data can be presented. The first point is to ascertain tenants' views on security of tenure and changes in 1These comments refer only to Harijan allottees: the Minas (Scheduled Tribe), faced no problem. Allottees cannot dispose of their land; it may be sold only to other Scheduled community members. This is to prevent exploitation by the higher castes. Some people sold plots to wealthier caste fellows but most lie unused or have been encroached upon by caste Hindu farmers. Similar cases have occurred elsewhere. See N. K. Singh, "Madhya Pradesh: Hunting the Harijans," Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. IX, #47 (November 23, 1974), pp. 1937-38. 112 employment. Next, the discussion is focused on wages earned, days worked, and the farmers' perceptions of their labor requirements. Of all respondents, 52.2 percent (N=35) try to lease in land when- ever they can. Of these around half are landless and 74.2 percent of the rest own less than five acres. In the year field work was done, two-fifths of the landless were unable to lease any land. Of all leasees, 66 percent were able to get between one and four arid acres. The rest save two persons got between four and eight acres of arid land. The two exceptions were able to get irrigated land of less than four acres. This means that except for these two, all tenants had land for only the monsoon crop. How difficult is it to lease in land? Two questions were asked: is it easier to lease land now compared with five or six years ago, and what are the rents charged and have they changed in the same time per- iod. In answer to the first question, tenants' perceptions point over- whelmingly to increasing difficulty in leasing land. Of all tenants, 91.4 percent say it is more difficult to get land now. Why? Three rea- sons dominate and these are given in Table 4.1. Aside from these, there were one or two other comments illustrating why there is more demand for land. Even with one mediocre monsoon crop of millet a man can provide a good part of the food his family needs during the year reducing the amount of cash required for purchasing grain. Such cash as might be earned from casual labor can then be used for other purposes. What are the terms of tenancies? Rents are normally paid in kind as a fraction of the gross production. Should there be a drought or crop failure the tenant may still be liable to pay a cash rental of 113 TABLE 4.1 REASONS WHY IT IS MORE DIFFICULT T0 LEASE LAND* Percentage of Reasons Tenants in Agreement l. Mbre people want land now (general population increase) 11.4 2. Owners are reluctant to lease because of profitability - prefer to self-cultivate to keep profits 68.6 3. Owners are afraid of tenancy provisions and so will not lease 33.3 4. Owners charge too high a rent and so tenants cannot afford to lease 14.3 5. More peOple want land because of a lack of alternate employment 11.4 6. Because of tractors owners do not want tenants any more - they can self-cultivate 25.7 *Respondents could give more than one reply and so total is not 100 percent (N=35). between Rs. 2.00 to 4.00 ($.26tx)$.50) per bigha leased.1 In the sample, of those able to get land that year, 68 percent paid a one-half share to the owners. The rest are fairly evenly divided between one-third or one-fourth shares, or cash payments of Rs. 2.00 to 6.00 ($.26 to $.75) per bigh_. Those paying cash are in the minority. One man paid three- quarters of the gross since he leased irrigated land. Another is a farm manager receiving a cash salary each month though he thinks of himself as a landless tenant. lIn Hanumangarh, 1.6 bighas (standard) equals one acre; in Shiv- pura, 2.5 bighas (standard) equals one acre. Thus the higher rental rate applies generally to Hanumangarh and the lower to Shivpura. 114 If tenants pay this much rent, what inputs do owners provide? In 70 percent of the cases owners provide nothing. In 16 percent of the cases tenants are given water, or fertilizer, or both. Some are able to use owners' plows, bullocks, or other hand tools. This supports the contention made earlier that owners are not interested in investing in their tenants' productivity. The best land is kept for self-cultiva— tion or is put under a manager's care. Landowners involved in money- lending are more interested in income from debts owed or the grain trade rather than land investments. Landowners sometimes mention that they do not invest more in their farms because of insecurity caused by the ten- ancy laws and ceiling legislation. This does not appear to be valid here despite landowners' protestations to the contrary as they are able to evade both bodies of law successfully and without much effort. Have leasing arrangements changed in any way other than land avail- ability? For about 10 percent of all tenants, there has been no perma- nent change though particular landowners may vary their terms. For 72 percent however, rents have risen dramatically over the past five to six years. For 95 percent of these, the rental medium has also changed. Previously landlords were interested in cash rents whereas now they increasingly demand payment in kind. This reflects the rise in grain prices -- from the landlord's perspective it is more profitable to be paid in grain which he can store until prices rise further in mid-season. As one tenant said, "Our fortunes run counter to everyone else's. In those days it was harder for us to pay in cash -- who had cash then? Today cash is easier for us to give as we can sell surplus grain at higher prices, but that is precisely why landlords want the grain." Obviously tenants prefer the lower rents of several years ago even if 115 they were in cash. "That much we could borrow if necessary. How do we borrow half of a crop?" There are thus several constraints on tenants wishing to lease land. One is the overall availability which is restricted given land- owners' preferences for self-cultivation. Secondly, the tenancy provi- sions create insecurity for the tenant. Third, there is the constraint of high rental rates which in part reflects population pressures on land. With high grain prices more persons want to lease land too which raises rents. With less employment for laborers (see below) they have an increasingly hard time saving the cash needed for seed and other inputs, and this combined with high rents has made it too difficult for some to lease land at all. Finally, the availability of large tractors for either purchase or hire, makes tenants increasingly obsolete. Agricultural Employment The effects of agricultural change on employment patterns are shown in Table 4.2. TABLE 4.2 WHETHER AGRICULTURAL LABORERS FIND MORE OR LESS EMPLOYMENT IN AGRICULTURE NOW THAN PREVIOUSLY Strata Changes in Employment Mbre Less No Total Employment Employment Difference Z (N) Owner-cum-laborers 54.5 36.3 9.1 99.9 (11) Landless laborers 10.0 80.0 10.0 100.0 (20) Overall 25.8 64.5 9.7 100.0 (31) 116 Included in this table are only the persons who normally work as farm laborers for wages. Significantly, most of those who find it easier to get employment in agriculture now are owner-cultivators who take on additional work to supplement farm incomes. Often because they are owner-cultivators they are better integrated into farming networks. None are Harijans or regular farm labor. Those finding it easier to find employment now point to the extension of irrigation facilities and consequent double cropping. Some mention that though farmers self- cultivate more, this has increased employment somewhat: "So many zamindars are farming seriously now since they can made money from it. Before they wouldn't even use all their land -- or even lease it. Now they have brought more into cultivation. They do not like to give it out on lease but prefer to take the tractor on hire for the plowing and manage it themselves or hire a manager for the year. But at least if they cultivate more land, there is more work at weeding and harvest time."1 Seven persons (22.6 percent) however, who normally work in agriculture were unable to find any employment in the fields that year. Of those facing employment difficulties in agriculture, most feel their problems are due to higher wage levels asked by laborers. Farm- ers are perceived to hire fewer persons doing more of their own work. Others say that rather than wages farmers want to keep their profits and so work more themselves. There is a difference here in the two villages. While Hanumangarh workers cite higher wages and farm profits as the main reason they cannot find employment, in Shivpura every laborer first men- tions the coming of tractors and other mechanical implements. Some 1The use of the word zamindar is colloquial here. This does not refer to the legal term of intermediary landowner. Farmers and labor- ers tend to use it for anyone who owns consequential amounts of land. 117 persons in Hanumangarh also mention these factors, but mechanization has gone further in Shivpura. In Hanumangarh the coming of farm machinery is associated primarily with the loss of tenancies; in Shiv- pura it is associated with an overall drop in employment. With labor— ers hired only for weeding and harvesting, 73.3 percent of the laborers in both villages estimate they can find work in agriculture for a maxi: .EEE.°f 120 days each year (two crops per year). For the rest of the time they rely on other casual jobs. Unlike laborers in other parts of the country, these farm workers are not necessarily tied to any particular landowner. Some owing debts they are unable to pay may find themselves in a position of working for a single person until the debt is repaid. For the most part however, laborers work wherever jobs are available. Sometimes certain farmers may be more prompt in payment of wages or give workers small fringe benefits such as cigarettes or tea during the day thus attracting more workers. During harvest most persons are able to find work in their own or neighboring villages unless drought or some other disaster has affected the crop. If most respondents can find work in agriculture for only about 120 days each year, what are they earning and what sources of employment are open to them for the rest of the time? Wage rates are similar in both villages: only during the very peak of harvesting do laborers in Shiv- pura receive half a rupee more than those in Hanumangarh. Payments may be made in either cash or kind though farmers prefer to pay in cash, and kind payments are calculated on the basis of cash equivalents. During harvest, laborers are paid Rs. 3/- per day for men ($.40), and Rs. 2.50 for women ($.33), and the amount is one rupee less for weeding and other 118 farm operations. In Shivpura if a farmer is not able to rent a tractor for plowing and has to hire a plowman, he has to pay between Rs. 80-100 ($10.66 - $14.66) for ten days of plowing.1 In Hanumangarh almost all wages are paid in cash whereas in Shivpura, wages during the monsoon crOp are paid in cash and those during the winter are given in kind. This reflects the market price of grains produced: wheat and barley grown in the winter are higher priced than millet (monsoon crop). It is to the producers' advantage to pay in kind for the higher priced grains since for each rupee value he gives away less grain. Tenants and labor- ers prefer the mixed payment system because they receive some minimal amount of grain for their own use and can then use cash for purchasing other items.2 There is no consistent alternate source of employment open to labor. Some find work on a casual daily or piece work basis: tending goats, drawing water, thatching roofs, or doing other odd jobs. The more fortu- nate might find work on a construction or road gang. Laborers from Shivpura often travel as far as Delhi (80 miles) or Chandigarh (around 1Farmers with larger holdings are especially in need of assistance of plowing because of the time factor. The rate comes to approximately Rs. 10/- per day ($1.33) for the plowman, his plow and two or more oxen. Each team of oxen can barely do one acre per day. 2To give the reader some idea of the cost of living in the two vil- lages, here is a list of items with the prices as they were in 1972-73. In some cases as with the grains, a range is given to indicate seasonal fluctuations: Flour: wheat - Rs. l/- to Rs. 1.60 per kilo (approxi- mately two pounds) ($.13 to $.21); millet - Rs. 0.80 to 1.30 per kilo ($.11 to $.17); Lentils: Rs. 2.50 to 4.00 per kilo depending on vari- ety ($.33 to $.53); Mustard oil: Rs. 4 to 8 per kilo ($.53 to $1.06); Kerosene oil: Rs. 1.00 to 3.00 (black market) per litre ($.13 to $.40); Cloth: for women's skirts,Rs. 20 to 30 per four metre piece ($2.66 to $4.00); for shirts, children's clothing, etc., Rs. 4 to 12 and up per metre ($.53 to $1.60). 119 200 miles) searching for work in construction which pays as much as Rs. 8/- ($1.06) per day. This is the most lucrative work, yet most of what is earned goes into maintaining the laborers and their travel expenses. Their families are generally left in the village and what meager savings are left go to the village money-lender who has provided their suste- nance while the men are away. As expected, most laborers feel their wages are too low (75 per- cent) given both the work done and the cost of living. The rest say their wages are basically fair but most of these are owner-cultivators themselves who do agricultural work for supplementary income and hire laborers of their own. One man feels that high prices have hurt farmers also since many of the smaller ones have to buy extra grain on the open market. So how can one expect them to pay their laborers more? Social Change: The Creation of New Dependencies Many tenants and laborers had applied for land allotments under the schemes mentioned above for Scheduled communities. What happened to the Hanumangarh allottees has already been recounted. Most persons think the idea is basically good but feel it never can be implemented properly since landowners will not permit it. Many persons applied for land but only few received any: 64 percent of all tenants and laborers applied of which only 20 percent were given any. In Hanumangarh the size of the plots might be considered adequate, but in Shivpura the allotments are only two-fifths of an acre each -- about the size of a small backyard garden. Some of these are saline -- others have long since been encroached upon by other farmers who will not relinquish them. Beyond these problems some respondents feel land has not been dis- tributed properly. Though half say most of the allotments were made to 120 the landless for whom they are intended, others are convinced that plots were handed out illegally to persons who bribed the officials: those who already had land and thus the influence to get more. In Shivpura there is a uniformly sarcastic reaction: "The good plots we can't farm because someone else is already on them. The bad ones —- well, who wants one bigha of saline soil that is waterlogged as well? So what does it really matter who got the land?" Two points should be noted here. First, it has been argued by some economists that the marginal productivity of labor in peasant agri- culture is approaching or is zero.1 On this assumption, farmers obviously cannot be expected to hire any more laborers or even utilize their own time more fully on their farms. This assertion is untenable as is shown clearly by Myrdal and others.2 Even using indigenous seed varieties, there is a gap between what is actually produced and the potential. In both villages here, farmers are well aware that they can improve their production by cultivating more intensively which requires more labor input for the most part. Second, the net effect of land allotments is the retention of a tied labor pool for farmers with more land -- particularly when one notes the size and condition of the plots given out. Even if the allot- tees can farm these, they are not sufficient for subsistence and their lSee Theodore Schultz, Transforming Traditional Agriculture, op. cit., passim. The main argument here is that farmers make maximum use of their factors of production including labor. 2Gunnar Myrdal, Asian Drama, 0p. cit., p. 1253; Morton Paglin, "'Surplus' Agricultural Labor and Development: Facts and Theories," Th3 American Economic Review, Vol. LV, #4 (1965), p. 825; and M. R. Haswell, Economics of Develgpment in Village India (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1967), p. 72. 121 owners still have to rely on such employment as might be found on other people's farms. The size of plots and the investment required to make them productive suggests their purpose is to prevent destitution not to encourage productivity or even self-reliance.1 An important social and political implication of this is that the laborers are economically more dependent than ever on a landed elite that increasingly has less need for their services. Perhaps recognizing that there never will be sufficient land for all Harijans, government has provided loans for building homes or for the purchase of goats, chickens, pigs or other livestock for alternate sources of income. A good proportion of these loans are captured by Harijan leaders who use them either for building new homes (though many already own large stone and mortar houses) or for money-lending.2 These leaders increasingly resemble other village notables whose life- styles they emulate. Their homes are built in the "modern" style and in order to raise their social position they have stopped eating meat, drinking liquor and refuse to perform traditional tasks left to leather- workers such as tanning hides.3 lHamza Alavi finds a similar situation in the Canal Colony areas of Pakistan (from discussion with him, 1972), and Stavenhagen, op. cit., cites the same situation for ejidatarios in Mexico. 2It is frequently difficult to get precise data on this because of the sensitivity of some recipients. At least four of the five Raiger patels (headmen) however, got loans that year. Harijans make up 27 per- cent of the village pOpulation as of the 1971 census. 3Mleat, liquor and contact with dead bodies (hides) are all pollut- ing. Such changes in practices are documented for many upwardly mobile groups in India. See Lloyd [.and Suzanne Hoeber Rudolph, The Modernity of Tradition (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967). This does not imply that other castes treat these Harijans as one of them. Rather, such adaptations set leaders apart from the rest of the community whose "backwardness" they rely on for their own distinctiveness. 122 These leaders are the new intermediaries between the political system and the Harijan communities. They sit on the elected village councils,1 help decide community matters and most importantly, have a say in the disbursement of loans and allotments of land. Though some loans are taken by them, others are judiciously given out to enhance the leaders' prestige and support. Benefits do get spread in "devious" ways to the community at large. Even if a leader should get a loan for himself, he hires laborers from his own community to build his new home. By using other loans for money-lending, he is able to supply badly needed credit to those who cannot obtain it elsewhere while creating his own patron-client network on which he can draw politically. The Congress Party relies on these leaders to mobilize Harijan votes at election time. The manner in which governmental credit is used is open knowledge and the trade-off is political support in return for a distributive monopoly.2 The limits of this strategy are discussed below. Here it is sufficient to note that while Raigers, Chamars or Khatiks may present a united front to other castes, they are divided internally. Some divisions represent traditional rivalries between families and other local disputes. However, two qualitatively different divisions are emerging. One is between the emergent leadership discussed here (a sort of 1The councils all have provisions for "reserved seats" for Harijans in case they are not elected at large. In Hanumangarh two electoral wards coincide with the main Harijan residential areas; in Shivpura, though the lines are not as clearly established, there were at least four Harijan members. 2This is openly discussed by a number of "village leaders" who point out that it is "very profitable" to work for Congress during the elections. They may be reluctant to talk about the specific benefits they receive personally, but point to those received by others. 123 "petit-bourgeoisie") and the rest. The second is between the older and younger Harijans who see the first division as a result of the co-option of their elders. Upper caste monopoly over goods and services is being replaced by a small Harijan elite drawing its strength from the new distributive mechanisms established by a Congress-dominated political system. The provision of special funds and other schemes for Harijan communities instead of integrating them into the wider society, tend toward the creation of a new group of political entrepreneurs whose existence depends on the distinctions between Harijans and the rest. Returning now to the laborers: they themselves see their future as lying outside of agriculture. This feeling is stronger in Shivpura where they see mechanization displacing them and land allotments as token payoffs. The only possibility they see in the village is the growth of agriculture-related industry. The sarpanch (elected village headman) plans to open an oil press for locally produced mustard and the production of animal feed using oil cake and grain. These schemes might, according to the sarpanch's estimates, take care of around 20 percent of the landless, but they are not feasible until the road between Shivpura and Bharatpur is completed. "What will the rest do? And what will we all do in the meantime?" This is the constant question. Permanent outdmigration is not a solution for most laborers. It has already been mentioned that many of them do leave the village sea- sonally for work in the cities where only temporary work is available. This is because of (1) their lack of skills, and (2) the vast numbers of urban unemployed persons. Indeed the construction industry often relies on the cheaper, but seasonal rural migratory labor, and there is no security to the worker once the particular job is completed. Given the 124 expense of living in cities, these laborers cannot stay on indefinitely without employment. In fact several laborers interviewed have tried staying in cities for long periods of time hoping for permanent employ- ment and have returned home bitter and discouraged. If these are laborers' perceptions, what of those of the culti- vators who require their services? One-third of the owner-cultivators and those tenants who leased land in 1972-73 maintain they need a larger labor input. Most of the rest feel there is no particular differ- ence and two say they need less outside assistance (see Table 4.3). Of these, one says his family can handle more work now as his children are grown-up. The other says that since he uses tractors on hire for plow- ing and threshing and has a pump set, he no longer requires plowmen, men for irrigation with the traditional leathern bucket and oxen, or women for threshing. TABLE 4.3 WHETHER FARMERS REQUIRE MORE OR LESS NON-FAMILY LABOR NOW Strata Labor Required Total More No Difference Less N.A.* % (N) Large farmers 50.0 31.3 12.5 6.3 100.1 (16) Medium farmers 33.3 33.3 0.0 33.3 99.9 (12) Small farmers 26.3 31.6 0.0 42.1 100.0 (19) Tenants 20.0 40.0 0.0 40.0 100.0 (20) Overall 31.1 34.3 3.1 31.3 99.8 (67) *Includes tenants who could not lease land in 1972-73 and those farmers who rely entirely on family labor. 125 Extended or improved irrigation is the most important factor cited by farmers requiring more labor. Some have sunk new wells, improved old ones or bought pump sets enabling them to take a second crop. Only two or three mention they are using improved techniques requiring more intensive hand cultivation. Some persons point out that laborers today "... just do not work as hard as they did when wages were lower" -- the longer they take to finish a job, the more money they get. Also if they take a long time, more of their friends are employed. Cultivators were asked if the wages they pay out have risen, fallen or remained the same over the past five to six years. They were further asked if they feel laborers receive a fair wage. Everyone agrees that wages have risen, and on the issue of fairness, the sample is split.1 "Looking to grain prices now, perhaps they are not paid enough. How can_ people survive on three rupees a day, or five at the most if a man's wife also works? They usually need around two to three kilos of grain a day, and that in itself will take more than half of their wages. How much is then left for chillies or kerosene, let alone clothes? And then too, they don't work everyday. So in terms of current prices, they are not paid enough, but what can we do?" (50 percent) Cultivators' ambi- valence is clear. Combined with a sympathy is a defensiveness about their reluctance to raise wages any further. Few of the rest offer any reason for saying the wages are fair. lOne farmer is an exception. He carries on a system of payment in kind used by his father: five kilos of grain per man per day. This is the rate for grain harvesting and it is slightly less for weeding. Laborers like the payment in kind, but few will work only for him as they also need cash for the purchase of other commodities. This farmer estimates he hires around 25 different men over about twenty days during one cropping season. 126 When farmers maintain they need additional labor it does not follow they hire more persons. Smaller farmers in particular already hire fewer laborers. In most cases the additional requirement is met by trading work with farm neighbors. One would suspect this might be true elsewhere. Therefore, to calculate the employment potential of the new technologies simply by totalling additional man—days of work is not accurate. It might be a fairly good indicator if landowners control more than ten acres; where labor-sharing is restricted by the size of the plots. Most farmers however, do not have such large farms. More- over though the new agricultural technologies require more intensive cultivation, it is a minority of farmers who use them anyway. Even those who do, seldom use the full range of recommended inputs and prac- tices. Summary In conclusion, the data suggest the following trends. Tenancies are more difficult to come by. Legislation passed to protect tenants' rights has worked to their detriment and it does not appear to be enforceable. Indeed one is led to suspect that government is afraid of enforcing it as it might affect owner-cultivators who are seen as cru- cial to the aims of food production. Further the introduction of trac- tors particularly reduces the need for tenants. Farm mechanization has also lowered employment possibilities in agriculture though both former tenants and farm workers continue to be dependent on farm employment for their livelihood. The process is grad- ual but one in which the very loosening of economic ties between land- owner and tenant/and laborer makes the latter more dependent on the 127 former. The result appears to be the formation of a "tied" labor pool whose links with the village are strengthened by the marginal land allotments given them by government. Where economic ties are completely broken, the emergent Harijan elite replaces the old patron-client rela- tionship with a new one that further sets the Harijan community apart from the rest of the village. The points raised here need now to be related to how respondents perceive their own well—being in relation to others and that of the com- munity at large. 0f further importance is the sequence of causation in their minds. What has caused these changes and who is responsible for them? These questions are taken up in the following chapters. CHAPTER V PERCEPTIONS OF WELL-BEING Now that the effects of agrarian change on the adoption of new techniques, employment and the pattern of agricultural relations have been considered, we turn to respondents' perceptions of changes in their own lives, in those of others around them, and in the village generally. Of importance is the separation of private and public gain, the felt needs of respondents, and their perceptions of how these needs can be met. The link between economics and the political system is the place- ment of responsibility for economic change on the political system. Individual Levels of Well-Being A basic measure of change in one's life is one's level of well- being. It is a subjective measure which asks people to evaluate change in their situation over a period of time.1 The concept is a general one, and here it is broken down into three parts: general well-being, improvement or decline in diet, and rise or decline in income. Each respondent was asked to evaluate his situation in relation to these and further asked why he feels the changes have occurred. First, respondents were asked if they feel they are better off now, worse off, or if there is no particular difference between now and five to six years ago. The results are presented in Table 5.1. The most 1Time span is five to six years -- since the beginning of the intensive schemes. 128 129 striking point is that most people are either worse off or have seen no difference in their condition. Breaking down the findings by strata one sees that large farmers are the most evenly divided. A number of reasons explain this. TABLE 5.1 RESPONDENTS' EVALUATIONS OF LEVELS OF WELL-BEING Conceptions of Well-Being Sample Strata (in Z's) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall Better off 37.5 41.7 26.3 10.0 28.4 No difference 31.3 33.3 42.1 15.0 29.9 Worse off 31.3 _2§;Q_ _§l;§ __Z§;Q 41.8 Total (%) 100.1 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.1 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) Some of those who are better off use improved practices: seed, fertilizers, and have expanded irrigation facilities. Other farmers in this category point to the price rise of grains on the open market which has helped them. Those of the large farmers who feel worse off claim their crops have been affected by irregular rains.l It will be recalled from Chapter III that several farmers who have irrigation facilities will not use them during the monsoon season. They also maintain that 1It was mentioned in Chapter II that there had been drought for two years though neither village studied was declared to be under famine conditions. 130 while grain prices have risen, so has everything else.1 Larger farmers who feel no difference are those who have not tried new techniques or who hold that though they earn more from higher prices, their families have also grown. Increased household expenses eat up increased income. The middle—sized farmers are interestingzhmthat a slight plurality have seen their circumstances improve. Of these, most pointtx>increased irrigation, the use of new seeds, and chemical fertilizers. The same farmers who in Tables 3.1 and 3.3 use the new inputs report better levels of well-being here. Those farmers feeling they are worse off point to inflation and increased family expenses such as marriages. Most small farmers are either worse off or have seen no difference in their levels of well-being. Those who are better off have again either improved their irrigation facilities, or have tried the new techniques. Some use chemical fertilizers, and almost all are previous users of high yielding variety seeds. Most of those who see no improvement or a decline in their position feel this is because of inflation. Some point out that if they could get improved inputs their situation would not be so bad. They say their incomes have risen but so have other prices. Again a few incurred major ritual or other household expenses increasing their indebtedness. With tenants and laborers, the picture reflects the situation dis- cussed in the previous chapter -- most of them are worse off. The ten percent who feel they are better off have found permanent employment with a farmer's family as tenants-cum—farm managers. The reasons for 1The inflation rate for 1973 was 26 percent and in 1974, 18.8 per- cent. Taken from the Economic Survey presented to Parliament by the Finance Minister, C. Subramaniam, February 24, 1975. From "Economic Survey for 1974-75," The StateSman Weekly (March 1, 1975), p. 3. 131 the worse situation of the majority are the same as those cited in the previous chapter: they own no land, are increasingly unable to lease any, and employment in agriculture has decreased. They also cite infla- tion as a major factor. The overall figures indicate that less than one-third of the rural population in these villages feels its general level of well-being has risen in the past five to six years. This is despite the fact that both villages are good agricultural areas producing a surplus each year. Additionally, it seems the increase in levels of well~being is related to either expanded irrigation facilities, the use of new techniques, or both. Combining the findings of Chapters III and IV, it is also clear that access to the means of production and increased population is denied to the majority of agriculturalists. As stated, however, the indicator of well-being is a general one. It may act as an outlet for general complaints. One needs to look at income and food intake also. These two measures are taken to reflect both the subsistence strategy of cultivation (where the household is the main production and consumption unit) and partial involvement in a monetary market. These cannot be measured precisely either since there is no way to get accurate recall about food or income over the past five to six years. This is not seen as problematic here however, since people's subjective evaluations are more important in the formation of attitudes than objective indicators. This pattern resembles respondents' attitudes toward their general level of well-being which may be because the most important item of expenditure is food. Additional production may first be used in the home before any is marketed. The table also reflects the rise in grain 132 TABLE 5.2 RESPONDENTS' PERCEIVED CHANGES IN FOOD INTAKE Changes in Food Intake Sample Strata (in %'s) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall Eat better now 31.3 41.6 31.5 10.0 26.9 No difference 25.0 33.3 36.8 10.0 25.4 Ate better before ‘_43;§ 25.0 31.5 80.0 47.8 Total (%) 100.1 99.9 99.8 100.0 100.1 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) price on consumption. The change in laborers' wage payment from kind to cash has thrown them on to a monetary market for the most basic of all essentials, grain. They are victims of wide seasonal price fluctuations without the minimal cushion provided by kind payments.1 A number of respondents asked the author to eat dinner with them: the meal con- sisted of one dry millet chappati (unleavened bread), and perhaps a little watery lentils. Some of these families eat only once a day dur- ing the agriculturally slack season. If children get hungry in between, they are handed a bit of millet stalk to chew on which is slightly sweet when green. The final indicator of well-being used was income, and Table 5.3 shows the respondents' perceptions of what had occurred. 1To give the reader an idea of seasonal fluctuations, when field work was conducted, the prices of flour were the following: millet - Rs. 0.80 to 1.30 ($.11 to $.21); wheat - Rs. 1.00 to 1.60 per kilogram ($.13 to $.21). 133 TABLE 5.3 RESPONDENTS' PERCEPTIONS OF CHANGES IN INCOME Perceived Changes in Income Sample Strata (in Z's) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall Increased income 68.8 50.0 68.4 40.0 56.7 No difference 12.5 25.0 10.0 0.0 10.5 Decreased income 18.8 25.0 21.0 60.0 32.8 Total (%) 100.1 100.0 99.4 100.0 100.0 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) More persons in each category except tenants and laborers report an increase in income which is due to both the price increases in agri- cultural commodities and (for the laborers/tenants who fit this) an increase in the wage rates. Some point out their production has increased. The tenants and laborers who cite a decrease in income say this is due to their inability to lease land and the decline in employ- ment opportunities. Owner-cultivators in all categories reporting decreased incomes mention either crop failures due to the rains or increased family expenses. Combining the three indicators, it is clear that increased income alone is not a satisfactory indicator: partially because of inflation and also because of the subsistence nature of peasant agriculture. A combination, however, indicates that the intensive programs have made positive changes in levels of well-being for only a minority of villag- ers. Those able/willing to utilize the new techniques have profited. 134 After six years however, the benefits have accrued to less than one- third of the respondents' while the level of well-being is reduced for most of the tenants and laborers -- or another one-third. Respondents' Views of Others' Well-Being Equally important to people's perceptions is their idea of what has happened to others around them. This provides a relative standard against which they can judge their own position. Each respondent was asked first to state generally what kinds of people in his estimation are doing better now that five to six years ago. The question was open- ended and each respondent could give more than one reply of which the first two were coded (see Table 5.4). TABLE 5.4 GROUPS OF PEOPLE CONSIDERED TO BE BETTER OFF BY RESPONDENTS Groups Doing Better Sample Strata (in 2's) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall 1. People with a lot of land or 31.3 33.3 63.2 60.0 49.3 employment 2. Big farmers and businessmen 0.0 8.3 5.3 10.0 6.0 3. Everyone but farmers 6.3 0.0 0.0 5.0 3.0 4. Scheduled cas- tes (Harijans) 18.8 8.3 0.0 0.0 6.0 5. Most people 18.8 25.0 5.2 5.0 12.0 6. Don't know 25.0 25.0 26.3 20.0 23.9 Total (%) 100.2 99.9 100.0 100.0 100.2 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) 135 Even though respondents name rather general categories, it is clear that farming and access to the factors of agricultural production are considered important for economic well-being. Respondents who feel people with land and water have prospered, point to high agricultural profits. Anyone with basic agricultural resources should do well. MOre telling is Table 5.5 which shows respondents' evaluations of specific groups. Each respondent was asked whether he perceived each category's position to be better or worse off over the past five to six years. In Table 5.5 only the "better off" responses are shown and there were no "don't know" replies. The consensus is strong. Besides access to the means of agricul- tural production, respondents feel others such as leaders, politicians and government servants have prospered. The reasons why they feel this way break down in the following manner. First, is the belief that most leaders, politicians, government servants and money-lenders come from landed families and use their posi- tions to enrich themselves. Elected officers use inputs on their own farms and share them with larger farmers and/or local leaders who help them get elected. The same is true of government servants -- to stay in the good graces of village leaders, they cater to their needs. Even if others request assistance, no one pays any attention. Those govern- ment servants who do not own land at least get regular salaries. If they feel the salaries are insufficient, they take bribes. In any case, none of these persons has to face unemployment as landless persons do, nor do they have to deal with the vagaries of weather and pests as do the farmers. Again, the point is that if one has more resources to begin with (land in the rural context) one is in a position to bargain 136 TABLE 5.5 PERCENT OF SAMPLE STRATA PERCEIVING SPECIFIC GROUPS ARE BETTER OFF Specific Groups Evaluated Sample Strata (in Z's) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall 1. Leaders and politicians 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 2. Government servants 87.5 100.0 89.5 100.0 92.5 3. Big farmers 93.8 91.7 94.7 90.0 92.5 4. Money-lenders 68.8 83.3 89.5 100.0 86.5 Skilled or semi- 3killed lab°r 56.3 61.6 78.4 40.0 59.7 (masons, carpen- ters, etc.) 6. Small traders or shopkeepers other 50.0 75.0 78.9 80.0 71.5 than money-lenders 7. Small farmers 31.3 50.0 31.6 15.0 29.9 8. Landless agricul- tural tenants 6.2 25.0 21.1 0.0 11.9 9. Landless agricul- tural labor 25.0 25.0 31.6 10.0 22.4 10. Old landlords (jagirdars) 25.0 58.3 36.8 50.0 41.8 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) for the means to increase one's level of well-being. Without basic resources one is unable to get the attention of the official hierarchy responsible for the distribution of necessary inputs. Opinion is fairly uniform toward the fate of landless labor and tenants. Though some farmers feel these groups are better off since wages have risen, most say despite this prices have lowered their levels 137 of well-being. There is some recognition by farmers that employment opportunities in agriculture have decreased due to both the mechani- zation of plowing and threshing, and the reciprocal labor performed by some cultivators. Other laborers such as masons, carpenters and the like, are seen to have prospered because wages for skilled occupations are higher than agricultural wages, and have also increased over the past five to six years. A mason may get up to Rs. 8.00 ($1.06) per day in the city and only slightly less in the village. Villagers who have built new houses feel the change. It was pointed out in the previous chapter that laborers will try to find work in construction because it is more lucrative (though seasonal). Another point is the ambivalence shown toward the position of the small farmer by respondents in other categories. The feeling here re- flects the notion that one needs abundant land to prosper (also indica- tive of an extensive, rather than intensive cultivation mentality). Yet as was shown in Chapter III, small farmers work their land the most inten- sively, market more of their produce, and generally show more motivation to improve their production. The common response by larger farmers is: "Small men -- what can they do? Look how much land it takes to feed my household. They may be receiving better prices, but what can they sell, after all?" "You must have more than five or six acres of land. I don't know how these men survive. I need more land myself, but where is it to come from?" While there is sympathy for the position of the small farmer, the consensus of larger cultivators is that they as well as ten- ants and laborers will eventually have to leave the agricultural sector. A final point to mention here is that if one looks at Tables 5.4 and 5.5, they show a slight feeling that Harijans (scheduled castes) and 138 agricultural laborers are better off. The full import of this is dis- cussed in the following chapters. Here it should be noted this is the beginning of antagonism on the part of larger farmers who are also of higher caste against the special funds and projects channeled to the Scheduled communities. Of particular importance is the distribution of land allotments. In the year field work was conducted (1972-73) new land ceiling legislation was enacted limiting holdings to eighteen acres of irrigated land. This legislation combined with land allotments made large farmers angry with the realization that their land might be taken away only to be given to Harijans who in their eyes are not "real farm- ers". Perceptions of Changed Village Conditions The respondents were also asked if they thought the village was generally better or worse off now than five to six years ago, and why. The results are presented in Tables 5.6 and 5.7. TABLE 5.6 PERCEIVED CHANGES IN VILLAGE CONDITIONS BY SAMPLE STRATA Changes Seen In Villages Sample Strata (in Z's) Large Medium Small Tenants/ Farmers Farmers Farmers Laborers Overall Better off 62.5 91.7 84.2 50.0 70.2 No difference 12.5 0.0 10.5 0.0 6.0 Worse off 25.0 8.3 5.3 50.0 23.9 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.1 (N) (16) (12) (19) (20) (67) 139 TABLE 5.7 PERCEIVED REASONS FOR CHANGES IN VILLAGE CONDITIONS BY SAMPLE STRATA Reasons for Change Sample Strata (in 2's) Large Medium Farmers Farmers Small Tenants/ Farmers Laborers Overall WHY VILLAGE IS BETTER OFF: 1. High grain prices have benefitted farmers who form majority Village amenities: (schools, electri- city, health cen- ters, etc.) Better farm inputs and assistance to farmers More employment and people work harder The crOps have been good - weather WHY VILLAGE IS WORSE OFF: 1. High grain prices have affected people badly except for money-lenders who profit Crops have been poor Less employment and more corruption which hinders access to inputs DON'T KNOW Total (%) (N) 18.8 37.5 18.8 15.6 100.0 (16) 25.0 33.3 16.6 16.6 99.8 (12) 21.1 15.8 21.1 21.1 100.3 (19) 2.0 10.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 40.0 10.0 20.0 20.0 102.0 (20) 19.4 13.4 29.4 100.0 (67) 140 The reasons why respondents feel this way are given in Table 5.7. First, the condition of the villages is perceived to be dependent on their state of agriculture. The main reasons cited for both better and worse conditions reflect this. Within the strata there are inter- esting variations. Medium and small farmers generally feel the villages are better off and point specifically to higher grain prices and better inputs. Higher prices presumably mean more to them since (1) they mar- ket a higher share of their produce, and (2) incremental increases in income mean more than they do to large farmers who produce more overall (but not per unit of land) to begin with and have no problem meeting their basic household requirements. The tenants and laborers are split on the issue primarily because a number of them see their own position and that of their neighbors as representative of the whole village. These cite the adverse effects of high grain prices. For those who feel the villages are worse off, the reasons are what one might expect given previous responses. High grain prices are problematic to those having to pay them: tenants, laborers and small farmers who need to buy additional supplies during the year. This is also true of those who say "the crops have been bad"; the implication being that drought has raised prices. Village amenities are mentioned by some persons most of whom are in the large farmer category. Though agriculture is the dominant con- cern (determining the floor of subsistence) considerable impact has been made by services such as schools, health care, electricity and roads. The small farmers and tenants/and laborers who mention amenities reason along the following lines. Higher prices help farmers and inputs help those who can get them. Even if these persons are in the minority, 141 government has helped everyone by providing basic amenities. Who cared about providing villagers with such things before independence? Educa- tion in particular is important to a number of Harijans (scheduled castes) who make up the bulk of tenants and laborers, as it is an ave- nue of upward mobility. That most respondents see their villages as better off now points to their ability to separate private from public gain. This is impor- tant in understanding their political behavior to be discussed later. "I personally have gained nothing since we began elections, but look at the village. Who ever thoughtcflfeducating village children, let alone Harijan children?" Similar comments were made by almost every respon— dent at some point during the interviews. Respondents' Needs If this is how respondents perceive their own situations and those of others around them, what do they see as their immediate needs? Each person was asked to state three things he and his family would like to have the most. As can be seen from Table 5.8, it is difficult to rank- order the needs even though they are presented as such. Respondents were also asked to state what they think are the basic needs of their friends. The questions were open-ended (the first three responses were coded) and a number of the responses are seen as interrelated by the respondents themselves (see Tables 5.8 and 5.9). Looking at the two tables, one finds a high degree of consensus. The overall picture indicates the importance of agriculture to both the subsistence cultivator and the entrepreneurial farmers. The general attitude is that if one has land and other inputs, education, housing, credit and improvement of social status will follow. One has to 142 .mowmuamouoa aH cm>Hw .nwuz Ioon mo maHaoox .aoHuaouuoo mo aoHumovauum .moHuHaoam omMHHH> uwuuon cam whoa mo aonH>oua waHvsHoaHkx .AmvowMHuumE Amvuounwamv mm zoom momcoaxo waHvsHocH« .oum .momHaoum Hmuou H.COH c.00H o.QOH o.o0H o.o0H o.OOH o.OOH H.00H a.¢m a.m¢ o.OOH w.OOH H.OOH H.OCH N.OOH ANV Hmuoa «.mu c.MH o.m o.m~ 0.0 0.0 m.c~ m.m N.m o.m~ o.mm m.w m.nm m.Hm o.o 30:3 u.:ow\w:Hnuoz o.m m.H o.m o.oH 0.0 o.o 0.0 0.0 ~.m 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 o.o m.o mowm3 Houumn was uaoa%oHnam 0.0 m.q m.H o.0H o.o o.o m.m m.mH o.o o.o o.o m.w m.o o.o 0.0 mooHum umsoH um maouH uoasmcoo «kooamauowumm m.H 0.0 0.0 0.0 o.o 0.0 0.0 m.m o.o m.w n.0H 0.0 o.o m.e o.o uaoaaum>ow you lump hHHmuoamu ¢.MH c.0H m.qH o.o~ o.om o.o m.m m.m H.HN o.n~ o.o o.mN m.o m.~H m.wH unouo woumum m.H o.o 0.0 o.m o.o o.o o.o 0.0 o.o 0.0 0.0 o.c o.o o.o 0.0 HmHoom\mummo mo uaoam>oumaH m.q m.H o.o o.o o.m 0.0 m.oH 0.0 o.o m.m 0.0 o.o o.o 0.0 0.0 :OHumoswm m.m 0.0 0.0 o.m o.o~ 0.0 m.m m.m 0.0 m.w o.o 0.0 m.~H o.o o.o «hHHamu\mchsom m.Hm ~.Nm «.mm o.m~ o.mm o.o m.om m.mm w.mH o.mN o.om o.Hq m.nm m.mq m.on ooH>vm\musacH HumouHaoHuw< o.m m.q N.~m 0.0 0.0 o.OOH m.OH m.m o.~m o.o m.w 0.5H .o.o m.o w.wH vcmH m N H m N H m N H m N H m N H HHmum>o uonmq\mucmaoa muoeumm HHmam mumsumm ESHcoz mumaumm owumH muooz mo Howuo paw mumuum memmz mo mange mammz DM>HMUMmm .mazmnzommmm .w.m MHmHm .Nonz .ouo .mowHaon Hmuou IomHo mo wCHaomx .coHuasuuoo mo GOHumovauum .mmHuHaoam mmeHH> Houuon paw whoa “Om conH>oum wchaHoaka .vaomeuuma Amvuouswsmn mm zoom womdmaxo wchsHocH« H.0OH o.oOH m.wm o.o0H o.OOH c.00H H.0OH H.o0H H.00H c.00H m.mm m.mo H.00H H.ooH H.OOH ANV HmuoH N.mq m.0N m.0N o.mq c.0H 0.0 q.wo o.Nm c.5q N.Hq m.mm o.mN m.nm m.NH m.NH Boax u.aov\waH5uoz m.H 0.0 0.0 o.m o.o o.m 0.0 0.0 m.m 0.0 0.0 0.0 o.o o.o m.o momma umuumn paw uamahonam o.m o.m m.n o.m o.OH o.o m.m o.o m.m o.o 0.0 m.w 0.0 0.0 m.o mooHua HoBoH um mamuH Hoasmcoo «kooamauowumm m.H o.m 0.0 0.0 o.o o.o o.o o.o o.o m.w m.w o.o o.o m.o o.o udoaauo>ow sou lump hHHmnocmu o.NH «.mH m.o o.mH o.mH o.o m.m m.m m.OH o.mN m.w c.0H m.o o.mN o.o unmuo moumum o.o 0.0 0.0 0.0 o.o o.o o.o o.o 0.0 0.0 o.o o.o 0.0 o.o o.o HwHoom\mumwo mo ucmsm>ouaaH o.o m.H 0.0 0.0 o.n o.o 0.0 o.o 0.0 o.o o.o o.o 0.0 0.0 o.o aoHumosvm 0.0 0.0 o.o 0.0 o.ON o.o m.m o.o o.o m.w o.c o.o m.NH o.o 0.0 «hHHamm\wnHmaom m.MN w.H¢ «.mH 0.0m o.mq o.o n.0H o.Hm n.0H n.0H N.H¢ o.mN m.mm 0.0m o.om moH>vm\mu=maH HmuaanoHuw< o.m ¢.q m.qq o.o o.m o.mm m.m o.oH H.HN 0.0 m.w o.mN m.o m.o o.mN wamH m N H m N H m N H m N H m N H HHmHo>o Hoan\muamamH muoahmm HHmam muoaumm abHvoz muoaumm owumq mummz mo umvuo was mumuum wwooz mo mvaHM mHzmnzommmm wm Qm>Hmommm m< mommz .mmmmfio .m.m mHm