INDUSTRIALIZING AGRICULTURE: A ‘TYPOLOGY ' 0F ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM MANAGEMENT STYLE Thesis fer the Degree of Ph. D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY MAURICE E. VOLAND 1958 This is to certify that the thesis entitled INDUSTRIALIZING AGRICULTURE: A TYPOLOGY OF ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM MANAGEMENT STYLE presented by Maurice E. Voland has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for PhD degree in M28 y Date 4: 0-169 ABSTRACT INDUSTRIALIZING AGRICULTURE: A TYPOLOGY OF ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM MANAGEMENT STYLE by Maurice E. Voland The purpose of this thesis is to study the relation- ship between the farmer and his firm and the pattern of labor management practices that he utilizes. To do this, the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology is developed in which the polar types are characterized as being "Rigixi" and "Adaptive." In constructing these types, the back- ground came from existing literature and theory on farnl management, farm labor management and entrepreneurship, of the larger study. The constructed typology contains four sub-types: Social Participation, Farm Management, Labor Management, and the Farm as a Firm. The constructed Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology is operationalized through a series of 21 variables. The farmer entrepreneurs in the sample are scored as being either Rigid or Adaptive on each of these 21 variables. The composite of this scoring forms the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. To determine whether a more parsimonious indicator‘ may be developed, 12 variables that have either a change Maurice E. Voland or a time dimension are extracted from the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score and formed into a Change- Time score. The Change-Time score gives results very similar to the longer, more cumbersome Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score and thus may be substituted as a more parsimonious operationalization of the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology. In general, the utility of constructing a typology to assist in the explanation of the empirical world is demonstrated by this study. The Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology identifies the variables that are important in explaining the unique characteristics of the various types of farm operators. The utility of this continuum will come as it provides the basis for further investi— gation of farm management--farm labor management pheno- mena by other investigators. To test the utility of this typology, it was opera- tionalized as suggested above and correlated with a series of structural variables. In all, a significant relation- ship was found between six of these structural variables and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score or the Change- Time score. These six structural variables are: Size of Farm, Farmer's Relation to the Land, Number_of Locations Farmed, Educational Attainment of the Farmer, whether or not the farmer employs a Full-Time Hired Man, and the Level of Capitalization of the farm enterprise. Maurice E. Voland There was no significant relationship found between the scores and three structural variables tested. These variables are: Age, Number of Years Farmed, and whether or not the Farmer Devotes All of His Time to the Farming Operation. Although it would be desirable to cast the Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Score or the more parsimonious Change- Time score in the role of a predictive or independent variable, it was not possible to do so within the context of this study. The way in which the scores were developed would have led to extreme circularity if they had been placed in the predictive role in this study. However, there is evidence to indicate that those farmers who score high on either of the scores also will score high on Farm Management and Farm Labor Management ability. INDUSTRIALIZING AGRICULTURE: A TYPOLOGY OF ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM MANAGEMENT STYLE By I \ - E Maurice E: Voland A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY College of Social Science Department of Sociology 1968 Copyright by MAURICE E. VOLAND 1968 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would_like to express a sincere note of thanks to Dr. Harvey Choldin, my chairman, for the kind assist- ance and guidance he provided through the development of this thesis. Thanks also go to Dr. J. Allan Beegle, Dr. Sheldon Lowry, Dr. James McKee, and Dr. Daniel Sturt for their suggestions, assistance, and support. A special note of gratitude goes to the memory of‘ Dr. James R. Hundley who conceived the project from which this study grew. Without the inspiration received from Dr. Hundley in the early stages of the project, this study never would have been completed. His untimely death meant not only the loss of an imaginative and com- petent sociologist but also a close personal friend. Further, my thanks go to my family and, especially, to my wife Ellen who provided the support needed to com- plete the long and rocky road of graduate school. My many friends and colleagues here at Michigan State Uni— versity also receive a special vote of thanks; without their faith and support this dissertation might never have been completed. Finally, I would like to thank the Office of Man- power, Evaluation, and Research of the United States 111 Department of Labor whose support of the project entitled "A Study of Interpersonal Relations Among Managers and Employees of Fruit and Vegetable Farms With Emphasis on Labor Management Practices Utilized" made this thesis possible. Formally acknowledging my involvement with the Office of Manpower Policy, Evaluation, and Research, I do affirm the following: The material in this project was prepared under a Grant from the Office of Manpower Policy, Evalua— tion and Research, U.S. Department of Labor, under the authority of Title I of the Manpower Develop- ment and Training Act of 1962. Researchers under— taking such projects under Government sponsorship are encouraged to express freely their professional judgment. Therefore, points of view or opinions stated in this document do not necessarily repre- sent the official position or policy of the Depart- ment of Labor. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS. . . . . . . . . . . . . iii LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi LIST OF FIGURES. . . . . . . . . . . . . Vii Chapter I. INTRODUCTION. . . . . . . . . 1 History of Farm Labor in the United States . . . . . . . . . 2 The Agricultural Ladder . . . . . . 6 Projected Changes in Farm Labor. . . . . 9 The Problem . . . . . . . . l6 Significance of the Study. . . . . . . 20 The Sample. . . . . . . . . . . . 20 II. ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRMS . . . . . . . 29 Review of Entrepreneurship . . . . 29 The Nature and Utility of Constructed Types. . . . . . 35 The Constructed Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Types . . . . . . 38 Rigid Entrepreneurial Farm Firms . . . . 40 Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Firms . . . 55 III. THE ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRM CONTINUUM. . . 71 IV. STRUCTURAL FACTORS AND ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRMS. . . . . . . . . . . . 82 V. CHANGE—TIME AS A KEY FACTOR. . . . . . . 95 VI. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . llO BIBLIOGRAPHY. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 I. INTERVIEW SCHEDULE. . . . . . . . . . 12A II. OBSERVATION GUIDE . . . . . . . . . . INA LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1. Distribution of 23 variable Entre- preneurial Farm Firm scores. . . . . . 73 2. Distribution of 21 variable Entre- preneurial Farm Firm scores. . . . . . 76 3. Individual farm firms and their Entre- preneurial Farm Firm scores. . . . . . 78 4. Correlation coefficients for variables in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm score and their contribution to the sub-scores . 80 5. Distribution of 12 variable Change-Time score . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98 6. Individual farm firms and their Change— Time score . . . . . . . . . . . 99 7. Correlation coefficients for the variables included in the Change-Time score. . . . 101 8. Correlation coefficients for the structural variables and the 21 variable Enterpre- neurial Farm Firm Score and the 12 variable Change-Time score . . . . . . . . . 109 vi LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1. Graphic representation of the distri— bution of the 23 variable Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm score. . . . . . . . 7LI 2. Graphic representation of the distri— bution of the 21 variable Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Score. . . . . . 77 3. Graphic representation of the distri- bution of the 12 variable Change- Time Score . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 vii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The intensification of change within agriculture from that of a primarily technological revolution to a revolution that is affecting the total structure of the industry has raised many value questions. One such ques- tion that is uppermost deals with the future of the "fam- ily farm." A great deal of nostalgia surrounds the con- cept of the "family farm" and its rightful place within American society. However, when one looks critically at the changes taking place within agriculture, the question is not so much whether the "family farm" still survives as it was once known as it is redefining the question within the limits of new directions that the structure of the agricultural industry is now taking. To be competitive in the marketplace today, the agricultural producing unit must be an efficient user of land, labor, and capital. Traditionally, Agricultural Economists have dealt primarily with land and capital, and only recently have they shown a concern for labor productivity. However, little concern has been expressed for the type of organizational structure of the producing unit in which labor productivity might be maximized. Generally the individual who is directly responsible for supervising labor is largely responsible for produc- tivity and satisfaction. Within agriculture the farm operator not only has this responsibility for labor super- vision, but he also has control over the organizational structure of that particular enterprise. This is not true in industry where the supervisor of the labor force is an employee of the firm and does not have direct control over the organizational structure of that firm. The concern of this study will be with the employer and the relationship he develops with his employees. The "Human Relations" school of industrial labor relations has pointed out numerous organizational changes that can increase worker productivity and satisfaction. This investigation will point out some of the parallels that also apply to that industry known as agricultural pro- duction. Although the primary data for this study will be the relations between migrant agricultural labor and their employing farmers, direct parallels can be drawn to the employers' relations with full-time employees. History of Farm Labor in the United States The earliest settlers of the American Colonies were practically all Europeans who would not readily submit to the authority of others. These early settlers emigrated to this country to escape religious, political, or other types of Oppression and were not willing to relinquish this freedom to become subservient to an employer. With the abundance of new land available, all those who emigrated voluntarily were able to acquire property readily, thereby becoming free and independent. Even with the availability of enough new land so that all emigrants could become property holders, there were needs for additional farm labor at various times of the year. In the New England and the Middle Atlantic colonies, as in nearly all frontier settlements, the need for this seasonal labor supply was met to some extent by community cooperation. In these areas agriculture tended to be of a subsistence nature and no major attempts were made to develop a market economy. Only the surpluses not required for family consumption found their way into the market place, and then these were generally bartered for goods or services that could not be produced on the farm. However, Edwards points out that in the southern colonies where staple crops were raised on large plan- tations, the need for a large labor supply was greater.1 Consequently, from the earliest days of the Virginia Company, the supply of an adequate labor force was of prime concern. To provide this supply of labor, two primary methods were utilized: 1) the importation of lEverett E. Edwards, "American Agriculture--The First 300 Years," Farmers in a Changing World, 1940 Year- book of Agriculture (Washington, D.C.: Superintendent of Documents, l9AO),pp. 171-276. ' contract labor (indentured servants) from the continent; and 2) the beginnings of the slave trade involving Negroes. The labor-contract method of labor supply was deeply rooted in England, where wages had been fixed by statute, minors apprenticed, and vagabonds or other unfortunates bound out to settle debts. These contracted, or indentured, servants may be divided into two groups, voluntary and involuntary. Vol- untary indentured servants were those whose apprentice- ship was based on a free contract. They were limited to persons who were anxious to start a new life in America and were willing to sell themselves for a period of 5 to 7 years to shipmasters or immigration brokers in payment for their passage. German settlers, and occasionally those of other nationalities, sometimes voluntarily indentured themselves in order to obtain funds to make a more advantageous beginning on the frontier when they were ready and able to set up farming for themselves. Most of these "freewillers" came during the latter part of the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. The involuntary indentured-servant group consisted of debtors, criminals deported by order of English courts, and unfortunates who had been kidnapped. Edwards points out that: In general, these redemptioners came of good stock. Force of circumstances and social exploitation rather than lack of native ability kept them poor. As a rule, all they needed was freedom to raise in the social and economic realm.2 Generally, these indentured servants in the southern col- onies were provided with 50 acres of land at the end of their term of service and many then became prosperous farmers as well as mechanics, artisans, and merchants. The first trade in indentured servants in the col- onies took place in 1619 when the first group arrived in Jamestown.3 It was at this time also that the first black African slaves were brought to Jamestown by a Dutch priva- teer and the slaveholding tradition was born in the col- onies. Indentured service came to an end in the early nineteenth century and slaveholding nearly was outlawed later in the century. The profit in cash crops of the day-~tobacco, indigo, and rice--was declining while the costs of holding slaves were increasing. Since the slave- holder had to maintain the elderly as well as other dependent slaves, the margin of profit on slaveholding was a very slim one indeed. However, with the introduction of cotton as a cash crop and the development of the cotton gin in the late eighteenth century, slaveholding once again became a very profitable enterprise, thus setting the pattern for the next 70 or 80 years. 2Edwards, p. 180. 3Paul S. Taylor, "Plantation Laborers Before the Civil War," _gricultural History, Vol. 28, pp. 1-21. The Agricultural Ladder The concept of the Agricultural Ladder has been an important one in understanding the agricultural labor situation in the United States. However, this concept is bound up with as much fiction as fact, and too often only those on their way up the "Ladder” are considered while those on their way down are completely disregarded. This is pointed out cogently by Lee where he considers primarily upward mobility within the agricultural pop- ulation.“ The case of the hired man's moving to the level of tenancy and then to farm ownership is not the only one. Shannon indicates that it was not uncommon for the free- holder to lose his farm and move down to the status of tennant or even that of hired man.5 Up to the beginning of the eighteenth century, it was not uncommon for the hired laborer or the indentured servant to move up to farm ownership and become an inde- pendent farmer. However, at this point in the development of our social structure there were no rigid class lines in existence. As the social structure began to solidify and a definite class system came into being, this upward mobility became much more difficult.6 u Shu-Ching Lee, "The Theory of the Agricultural Ladder," Agricultural History, Vol. 21, pp. 53-61. 5Fred A. Shannon, American Farmers' Movements (Princeton: D. Van Nostrand Company, Inc., 1957), pp. 8—10. 6 Shannon, p. 9- During this period and up through the late nineteenth century, there were new frontiers continually available to the aspiring farm owner. Government lands were sold directly to potential farmers or to speculative combines who then resold the land to farmers. The total cost of this virgin land was quite small, even by the monetary standards of the day; however, due to the extreme diffi- culty the upwardly mobile farm hand had in assembling capital for_the initial purchase of land and the extremely tenuous and difficult credit arrangements, only a limited number of former hired farm workers was able to move up the "Agricultural Ladder" to full ownership. It was from this group, as pointed out by Shannon above, that there was a great deal of downward mobility as well. The extremely tight credit situation and the vagaries of the weather and markets forced many a fledgling farm owner back to tenancy or hired servitude. When looking at contemporary agriculture, the up- ward mobility within the farming population is even more limited. The extremely high capitalization required to begin a farming operation is almost prohibitive for any- one not moving into farming through inheritance. Another unique trend of recent times is for small farmers, who do not have the capital or the managerial ability to expand their operation to maintain a competitive position in today's agriculture, to sell their holdings to larger, more efficient operators and then go to work for them as hired employees-~many times continuing to work their former farms. It is this trend towards larger units that will be owned and/or managed by fewer men and the larger number of full-time as well as seasonal employees in the agricul- tural labor force that is the concern of this study. As the farm owner and/or manager takes on a hired labor force, he must develop additional skills in production and marketing that will be required by the competitive market situation, but even more important he must become a very efficient manager of labor since this is becoming one of the major costs of production. Sturt points out that labor costs on Michigan dairy farms come to about 20 per cent of total production costs.7 As industriali- zation of agriculture continues, the total prOportion of labor costs of some types of enterprises will decrease as technology replaces manpower, but the effectiveness of labor will be even more critical than it is today since labor, although more highly skilled, will still be required to operate the automated equipment now replacing large numbers of agricultural laborers. 7Daniel W. Sturt, "Farm Labor in 1980," Research Report A8--Farm Business, East Lansing: Agricultural Experiment Station and Cooperative Extension Service, Michigan State University, 1966, p. 9. As indicated above, downwardly mobile freeholders contributed one source of agricultural labor in the past. This is especially true within the realm of migratory, or seasonal, labor utilized in agriculture. Many of the participants in the migrant stream are sharecroppers who have been displaced by modern technology or former free holders whose operations were too small or too marginal in other ways to be competitive in today's economy. In addition, large numbers of Mexican nationals have partici- pated in the migratory labor force, either as contract laborers who returned to Mexico at the end of the harvest season or as illegal aliens who crossed the border without legal sanction. Substantial numbers of residents of the West Indies and Puerto Rico also have participated in the migratory labor force on a contract basis. In addition to these sources, large numbers of U.S. citizens of Mexican heritage from south Texas have traditionally been part of the hired agricultural labor force of that area and have entered the migratory farm labor force as a means of sup- plementing partial employment in their home area. Projected Changes in Farm Labor Although hired labor of one sort or another has been an important input into American agriculture since the earliest times, the prOportion and position of hired labor within American agriculture will be changing. As the industrialization of agriculture proceeds, the farm labor 10 scene will be one in which fewer numbers of farm operators will be providing a smaller percentage of the total farm labor requirement. Although the statement made by Hecht, that "Farming is the only major industry in which entre- preneur and members of his family make up a major proportion of the work force . . . ,"8 will still hold there will be an increasing number of enlarging farms and on these will be found an increasing number of regular employees. Fuller and Beale point out that: In the more distant future (say three to five decades) when the organizational revolution (that is, agri- business) approaches the plateau of its fulfillment, farm entrepreneurship will no longer be combined to any significant extent with working self-employment. Farmers will have become professional managers on their own account or will have been displaced by managements of integrated corporations that direct farm production and control input. The character of the available employable labor force in agricultural employment also is likely to change. Fuller and Beale suggest further that in addition to the technological revolution now underway in agriculture, there may very well be a human revolution in the making. They feel that contemporary human society maintains a more explicit concern for its people, whether viewed as productive 8Reuben W. Hecht, "Farm Labor Situation-Trends and Forces at Work," Lincoln: Paper presented at National Exten— sion Workshop on Farm Labor Problems, University of Nebraska Center for Continuing Education, Lincoln, Nebraska, Nov. 1-4, 1966, p. 1. 9Varden Fuller and Calvin L. Beale, "Impact of Socio- economic Factors on Farm Labor Supply," Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 5, December 1967, p. 1238. 11 human capital or as the disadvantaged and poor. They state that: The components of a deliberate national manpower policy are emerging, reflecting both the resource and the human interest . . . two prospective impacts follow: (1) departure from agriculture of the remaining surplus farmers will be made easier; (2) the supply-price of labor to farming will rise. Or, to put the latter more pointedly, the gap between the terms of farm and nonfarm employment will disappear.10 The present indices of production and production per unit of labor can be used to generate projected indices of labor input. By utilizing this projection method, Hecht esti- mates that on the average there will be 316 million workers 11 This in the U.S. engaged in farm employment in 1980. would constitute a 36 per cent decrease from 1965. Hired workers may average about one million, or a third less than the 1965 average. Farm operators and unpaid family workers also may decline a little more than a third or to about 2.6 million compared with 4.1 million in 1965. Overall need for farm labor will be less in the years ahead, Hecht believes, but higher skilled workers will be needed. Such jobs as operation and maintenance of increas- ingly complex farm machines and proper application of agri- cultural chemicals with increasingly narrower tolerance will require additional technical "know-how" and judgment. 10Fuller and Beale, p. 1238. llHecht, p. 16. 12 As measured over broad areas, seasonality of employ- ment of operators and family workers will continue to decline while seasonal employment of hired workers will probably increase slightly. In some areas there will always be a need for relatively large numbers of workers for short periods. When using linear projection methods to predict farm labor needs for Michigan, Sturt points out that with 1960 as a base, there will be a A0 per cent reduction in farm labor requirements by 1980.12 Further mechanization, increased opportunities for nonfarm employment, and the social and legislative environ- ment affecting the conditions of labor employment will influence the structure of the agricultural labor force. In 1959-63, 80 per cent of the agricultural labor was supplied by farm operators and their families while 20 per cent was hired. Approximately one—third of the hired labor during the peak season in the summer was supplied by year-round hired workers; seasonal employees supplied approximately two-thirds of the hired labor requirements. In 1980 the situation will be reversed with approximately 65 per cent of the agricultural labor supplied by year- round employees and one third by seasonal workers. The greatest seasonal employment will occur in September as opposed to June, July, and August as was the case in 1960. l2Sturt, pp. 9—1A. 13 Sturt states that in 1980 the farm labor situation will be characterized by: l. well-trained year-around workers capable of coping with the increasingly complex tasks brought about by greater mechanization; a sharp reduction in the number of interstate and foreign seasonal workers in favor of intra- state and local seasonal workers; shifts away from family work groups to all male teams of seasonal workers; increased wages, better housing, and better working conditions in general for all agri— cultural workers as agricultural employees compete for labor in a labor market dominated by the nonfarm economy; improved farm labor management practices in- cluding training programs for all types of workers and better supervision of workers as employees attempt to upgrade the quality of labor and step up labor productivity.1 The amount of labor required for different farm operations depends upon the size of the operation, the extent of mechanization, and the type of farm. As indicated earlier in this chapter the proportion of the labor costs to total production costs for the dairy farmer is much smaller than for a fruit or vegetable farmer. With the changes expected in the farm labor picture by 1980 and the concurrent changes in the structure of the agricultural enterprise to a more industrialized type, the question arises as to the possi- bility of unionization among farm workers. Speaking at the 1966 Agricultural Outlook Conference, Varden Fuller stated that there will be a number of constraints working 13Sturt, p. 9. 1“ against unionization of agricultural workers.lu Among these are the fact that farm employment will continue to be predominantly in small-scale, broadly scattered units. Employment in large numbers per farm unit seldom occurs except during temporary harvest period. Even where there are a small number of year-around employees on a production unit, these units will be rather widely dispersed. The nature of the farming enterprise places the workers in close contact with the employer. These factors of geo- graphic dispersion along with close employer-employee working relations are generally obstructive to union organization. In addition, seasonal workers have not been generally responsive to unionization appeals. Many expect not to be permanently in farm work and do not regard an improved future in farm labor as a goal worth striving for. Those who are resolved to a future in farm 1abor--by which one inevitably means the older, less edu- cated, and otherwise handicapped persons--are typically neither well prepared nor strongly motivated toward pur- poseful collective action. Without statuatory coverage, the cost of organization of farm workers will be prohibitive. Even if National Labor Relations Act coverage should be extended to farm l“Varden Fuller, "Emerging Farm Labor Issues," Wash— ington: Paper presented at AAth Annual National Agricul- tural Outlook Conference, 10:15 a.m., Tuesday, November 15, 1966. 15 workers, there will be a long period of adjustment required to develop a smooth and productive working relationship between the appropriate units, the farmers, and the rele- vant governmental agencies charged with enforcement and interpretation of the relevant legislation. In summary, Fuller says that: the assessment that seems reasonable to me is to expect a new and more broadly supported stride in the development of farm worker unions and col- lective bargaining, but under very substantial constraints. Initially, and perhaps for many years, the pattern will be quite spotty. Even so, the total impact of limited unionization may very well be greater indirectly than directly. Farm organizations are already increasing their appeals to members to upgrade employment prac- tices and conditions as a deterrent to union organization.1 In looking ahead to and beyond the farm labor picture in 1980, the salient changes seem to be that there will be roughly one third less labor required by agriculture than there is at the present time. The proportion of hired labor to farmer and family labor will be higher. There will be more full—time year-around hired laborers and smaller numbers of seasonal laborers. The seasonal laborers will be primarily male as opposed to a seasonal labor force made up of families as is the present case. The seasonal labor force will be predominantly an intra— state force rather than the present inter-state labor force. The impact of unionization will be felt, but due 15Fuller, pp. A—5. 16 to the dispersion of production units and the transient nature of the seasonal labor force, the impact of unioni- zation upon the agricultural labor force of Michigan will be limited. The Problem The following is a report of research designed to study the relationship between the farmer and his firm and the pattern of labor management practices he utilizes. As has been suggested earlier, much of the success of the farmer of the future will lie in his ability to organize his firm in such a way that he will be able to maximize the productivity of the labor input and minimize the cost of this input. A key to this is the farmer‘s ability to deal with hired labor in such a way that he is able to maximize worker productivity and satisfaction. This will hold true for both year-around hired labor as well as seasonal, or migratory labor hired during periods of peak labor needs. This study is based on a critical analysis of the data gathered for the study entitled "A Study of Inter- personal Relations Among Managers and Employees of Fruit and Vegetable Farms with Emphasis on Labor Management Practices Utilized." This study was conceived by the late Professor James R. Hundley of the Department of Sociology at Michigan State University and conducted jointly during 1967 by that department and the Rural Manpower Center of 17 Michigan State University. The specific objectives of the larger study were: To secure needed information for education and training action programs through research on the interpersonal dynamics of the work environment involving farm managers and seasonal farm workers. To determine the nature of the work environment for both managers and workers when certain manage- ment practices are employed and to determine how seasonal workers respond to and gffect the utili- zation of management practices.1 It has been pointed out earlier that a larger prOportion of the labor input in agriculture in the future will be in the form of hired labor than is now the case. When this changing proportion of farmer and farm family labor to hired labor is considered, it becomes even more obvious that the question of employer-employee relations in agri- culture will be a relevant one. Numerous studies have dealt with the structural and social psychological charac- teristics of farmers who adopt various innovations.17 Agricultural economists have made extensive studies of farm management from the economic perspective. There has been no research that integrates farm labor management with farm management, per se. It will be the focus of 16"A Study of Interpersonal Relations Among Mana- gers and Employees of Fruit and Vegetable Farms with Emphasis on Labor Management Practices Utilized," Pro- posal submitted to the Director, Office of Manpower, Policy, Evaluation and Research, U.S. Department of Labor, by Rural Manpower Center, Michigan State University, East Lansing, May 12, 1966, p. i. 17Everett M. Rogers, Diffusion of Innovation (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1962). 18 this research to integrate the study of farm labor manage— ment with the more specific field of farm management as viewed by the agricultural economists.18 The farmer will 18It is not feasible to fully review the total lit- erature in farm management and farm labor management, but representative works which might be cited are: Varden Fuller, Labor Relations in Agriculture (Berk- eley: Institute for Industrial Relations, University of California, 1955). Harland Padfield and William E. Martin, Farmers, Workers and Machines: Technological and Social Change in Farm Industries of Arizona (Tucson: The University of Arizona Press, 1965). John H. MacGillivray and Robert A. Stevens, Agricul- tural Labor and Its Effective Use (Palo Alto, California: The National Press, 196A). C. E. Bishop, ed., Farm Labor in the United States (New York: Columbia University Press, 1967). Willard T. Rushton and E. T. Shaudys, "A Systematic Conceptualization of Farm Management," Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 19 (February, 1967), pp. 53-63. Papers presented at the 1965 annual meeting of the American Farm Economics Association, Oklahoma State Uni— versity, Stillwater, Oklahoma, August 22-25, 1965, as reported in Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. A7, December, 1965. Myron P. Kelsey, "The Management Factor in Commer- cial Agriculture, Is It an Art or a Science," pp. 1U33—36. J. C. Headley, "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture, How Can It be Recognized," pp. 1437-39. M. F. Quenemoen, "The Management Factor in Commer- cial Agriculture: The Influence of Values and Goals," pp. 1440—42. Dale E. Butz, "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: The Effects of Off Farm Employment Inputs," pp. lAA3-45. Aaron G. Nelson, "The Management Factor in Commer- cial Agriculture: How Can It be Improved," pp. lAA6-A8. Robert E. Rieck, "The Management Factor in Commer- cial Agriculture: How Can It be Taught," pp. 1449-51. Rex P. Kennedy, "The Management Factor in Commer- cial Agriculture: New Tools for the Manager," pp. 1A52- 5 . 19 be viewed as an entrepreneur since this perspective seems best to fit the type of organization presently found in 19 To achieve this objective, a American agriculture. typology of farm firms will be developed. This typology will be so formulated that it will allow for the influence of the farmer (entrepreneur) on the firm. The background for this typology will come from existing literature and theory on farm management, farm labor management, and entrepreneurship, but the typology itself will flow from Q the data gathered for this study.’0 19After an exhausting search through the literature of Complex Organizations and Bureaucracy, I became pain- fully aware that the farm of today is not structured in such a way that the theory and literature from this area of Sociology is applicable. While the organizational structure of agriculture is becoming more complex, the average farming operation is not structured in such a way that this body of theory and literature will help to ex- plain what is going on. Consequently, the body of litera- ture dealing with Entrepreneurship seemed to offer the tools for providing the understanding and insight needed to understand the organization of farms in this study. As will be noted, a number of the farms included in this study are approaching the organizational complexity where the theories of Complex Organization and Bureaucracy might have explanatory power, but the bulk of the farms have not reached this point as yet. 20This type of formulation follows the criteria set down by: Barney G. Glaser and Anslem L. Strauss, The Discovegy of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Quantitative Research (Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 1967T1 John C. McKinney, Constructive Typology and Social 'Theory (New York: Meredith Publishing Company, 1966). 20 Significance of the Study Through the investigation of farm labor management styles, this study will contribute in a modest way to our understanding of the intricacy of this problem. It will demonstrate the utility of the constructed typology as a research tool that can bring greater understanding to the complex organizational and labor management approaches that are present in today's agriculture. In addition to the development of a constructed typology of the farm firm and the theoretical implications that will flow from this construct, it will help to lay the basis for ameliorative programs which may increase the satisfaction of both employer and employee in the agricul- tural setting. The Sample A stratified random sample of 100 farms that held Migrant Labor Housing licenses during the 1966 growing season was drawn. Interviews were completed with 76 of the original farm operators included in the sample. Of those 24 cases that were not included ten had gone out of business since the summer of 1966, six changed their mode of Operation so that they would not be employing migrant labor during the 1967 growing season, and eight were out of the state and not available for interview during the inter-viewing period. 21 Due to the budgetary limits of this study, no sub- stitution was made for these 24 cases. However, in the view of the principal investigator the 76 cases included in the study are considered to be representative of all farm operations that utilize migrant agricultural labor. The research design called for the selection of a limited number of this original sample of farms to be re— contacted during the harvest season. At this time obser- vations of the work flow of the farm and supervision style of the farm operator were recorded and interviews with members of the migratory labor force working on that farm were conducted. Consequently, a purposive sample was drawn from the original sample that would represent pro- portionally by size of crew and crops harvested all fruit and vegatable farms in the state that utilize migrant labor for harvest purposes. Migrant laborer heads of households and single males over 16 years of age who were not traveling with their families were interviewed on the 38 farms included in this purposive sample. A total of 238 interviews was completed with migrant laborers. For the purposes of this dissertation, only that data gathered from the 76 farms included in Phase I of this study and relevant case study data from the obser- vations of work flow and supervision style carried on in Phase II will be utilized. However, for a more complete understanding of the sample, the following summary will 22 highlight some of the unique information that came as a result of the combination of research methodologies. The qualitative richness of much of the case study data is lost in a quantitative analysis and it will be our purpose here to show some of this rich body of data gathered through depth interview, observation of work flow and supervision, and insight gained by the research team into the situation facing the horticultural specialty crop farmer in Michigan today. To be successful in the competitive climate of agri- culture today, the farmer must be extremely efficient and flexible in organizing the resources he requires to main- tain and enlarge his business. One would expect that edu- cation would play an important part in helping the indi— vidual farmer do a more efficient job of organizing these resources. The analysis of the interview protocols as well as the observations carried on during Phase II of the study would tend to bear this out. While the farmers under age A5 had higher educational attainment than did those who were age A6 and over, when we look at the group who had obtained education beyond the twelfth grade we find that 26 per cent of the younger group and 16 per cent of the older group had obtained some education beyond high school. This exposure to higher education extended from as little as one semester all the way to graduate education. The analysis of the interview protocols and personal contact with the farmers during the second phase of the 23 study strongly reinforces the contention that formal edu— cational training helps the individual farmer to more efficiently organize his resources in order to be com- petitive in today's agriculture. The type of higher edu- cational exposure did not necessarily seem to make a great deal of difference when it came to evaluating success. The farmers included in the study who had been exposed to higher education had a top-heavy exposure to training in technical agriculture, while a background in liberal arts, education, or business was not uncommon. While the bulk of the farmers in this group had been exposed to training in technical agriculture, they all tended to agree that the most useful training they had received was in the areas of economics, business (with an emphasis on manage- ment), and communications. Background in these academic areas often is cited as being important for anyone who is involved in management, whether it is in business, industry, government service, or in agriculture. The innovativeness of the farmer seemed to be closely tied to his educational level. While the adOption of technical innovations did not necessarily seem to be con- nected with any particular educational level, those inno— vations that required a change in the organizational struc- ture of the farm business seemed to be very closely related to that group of farmers who were most highly educated-- and.here the educational attainment rather than the age of the farmer seemed to be the most important factor. 24 On the technical level those innovations which seemed to crop up most often were the adoption of new harvest and tillage techniques; the adoption of new insec- ticides, herbicides, and fertilization programs; and the adoption of new strains or varieties of crOps. On the other hand, there is a group of innovations that requires a major change in the structure of the farming enterprise, a group which includes the extension of the farmer and his firm into the direct marketing of his produce. The farmer moves from a strictly production orientation to one where he packages not only his own produce but con- tracts with other growers for this service, thus estab- lishing a genuine chain of command among his employees so that he has others to call upon when making decisions relative to the total enterprise and can delegate certain decision—making powers to various individuals within this chain. While a number of the farmers were moving in the direction of shared decision-making and a few actually had established this policy, a large number were substi— tuting mobility and instant communications for a more highly structured organization. While they had estab- lished a chain of command, they had given the individuals within this chain only limited decision—making authority. To substitute for this more complex organizational struc- ture they relied upon Citizens Band radios to keep them 25 in direct communication with all phases of their operation. In this way, even though the farming operation might be dispersed over a large geographic area, the farmer would be able to move from one site to another in no more than 10 or 15 minutes and be on hand for decisions requiring his presence. Also, the flexibility of radio communications made it possible for him to assess a situation and make relevant decisions many times without having to travel to the site where the decision was required. Again, there seemed to be quite a high relation between educational attainment and the level of decision- making that the farmer was willing to share with his employees. These differences do not seem as distinct in the quantitative analysis of the data later in this study, but they seemed to be particularly strong when the case study materials and observational materials were reviewed. What has been said in regard to the adoption or the invention of innovations might also be said about the relations between the farmer and his employees, both full- time and seasonal or migratory employees. Those farmers who seemed to demonstrate the greatest flexibility in ability to organize their farm business also were the ones who tended to have the best relationships with their hired employees. The idea of shared decision-making has been indicated above, but perhaps even more important is the attitude that the farmer has towards his employees. 26 Attitudes ranged all the way from bare toleration of em- ployees, whose only purpose was to do the job, be quiet, and move on, to acceptance of these employees as unique individuals able to make unique contributions to the busi- ness enterprise. Farmers with this latter attitude created an organizational structure in which these individuals could perform at their highest level of effectiveness. This attitude also could be measured in the various fringe amenities provided by the farmer to his employees-—these generally include housing for both full-time as well as seasonal employees, insurance programs, job security pro— grams, and wages in general. While the most flexible farmers did not necessarily pay the highest direct wage to their employees, they did provide the beet quality housing and the most flexible and complete insurance and retirement programs. They provided paid vacations for full-time employees and in general dealt with employees as individuals who had unique capabilities and problems and not just as a stereotype of what a farm worker is. The Minimum Agricultural Wage legislation that became effective during the period of the field work for this study produced quite varied results. One typical response was that "this is the biggest and most recent blow against the free enterprise system--it's going to drive us out of business," while others responded, "It's too bad that it had to come to this, but in the long run 27 everyone will benefit since now I have a base to work from in setting wages and it will better help me to project my costs of production." As might be expected, those farmers who were most against this legislation were the least effi— cient and effective operators while those who took the legislation in their stride were the most flexible and pro- gressive. From the workers' side this legislation generally raised their overall take-home pay and limited the necessity of their shopping around for the farmer paying the highest wages since everyone was paying pretty much the same, especially for seasonal or migratory work. For the farmer, it meant that he did not have to worry about his harvest crew's picking up and leaving for a place where wages were significantly higher since everyone was paying nearly the same wage. However, the amenities provided by the farmer in such forms as housing, insurance programs, and recrea- tional facilities became even more important in this con- text. The farmers now were forced to provide superior fringe benefits if they were to have a happy and satisfied crew since wages had been stabilized. In general, included in this study are some of the most flexible and progressive fruit and vegetable farmers in the state of Michigan as well as some who are only in business through the grace of their creditors or because they are willing to live on a subsistence or lower wage. All indications are that in the future it is the flexible, 28 progressive farmer who will dominate agriculture in not only Michigan but the country and the rigid, inflexible farmer will either be forced out of business by the pres- sure of the market place or more general changes taking place within agriculture. While it has been true up until now that the farmer is the only businessman who has been able to operate in an inefficient and ineffective manner because he owns and controls all of his resources of production, this may not be as true in the future when the flexible, progressive farmer will need to look to others for some of these resources of production. CHAPTER II ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRMS Review of Entrepreneurship Historical Development of the Concepp The term or concept "entrepreneur" has been used for some 300 years by social scientists, especially economists. The usage and meaning applied to the term during this period of time has varied. Economic historian Fritz Red- lich says that the term was first used in a dictionary of commerce written in 1723 by Savary.l At that time, "entre- preneur" was defined as the individual who purchased goods or economic utilities for fixed prices when he did not know at what price he could sell these items. A review of the concept of entrepreneur as it has been used in modern times is provided by Bert F. Hosel- itz.2 To many economists, the concept of entrepreneur has been utilized to denote the risk bearer, and in many cases it has been abstracted so far that the flesh and lFritz Redlich, "The Origin of the Concepts of Entrepreneur and Creative Entrepreneur," Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, Vol. 1, No. 2 (19H9), pp. 1-7. 2For various theories and definitions of "entrepre— neur" see Bert F. Hoselitz, "The Early History of Entre- preneurial Theory," Explorations in Entrepreneurial His- tory, Vol. 3 (1951), pp. 193-220. 29 30 blood have been taken from the concept. Risk-bearing is considered a function of the business firm and not neces- sarily the function or activity of an individual. Further, the assumption has been made by some that the entrepreneur is the firm.3 In contrast, Schumpeter uses the term pri- marily to denote the function of activity of innovation.” This definition has been accepted by many writers and the line of thought has developed that the entrepreneur is the innovator who is creative in the sense of doing something new or untried. Much of the popular literature character- izes the entrepreneur as an individual who is creative, daring, aggressive, and willing to take chances. It is associated with the rags to riches theme, that of the cul- tural hero found in the Horatio Alger myth. In the eyes of some, it also has the connotation of being on the mar- gin of dishonesty or sharp trading.5 Most of the defi- nitions of entrepreneur reveal little of the man to whom the title is given. The school of thought represented by economic historian Arthur H. Cole focuses more direction 3J. H. Strauss, "The Entrepreneur: The Firm," Jour- nal of Political Economy, LII (19AM), pp. 112-127. “Joseph H. Schumpeter, "Economic Theory and Entre- preneurial History," Change and the Entrepreneur (Cam- bridge: Harvard University Press, 19A97, pp. 63-84. 5R. Richard Wohl, "The Rags to Riches Story: An Episode of Secular Idealism," in C1ass,,Status and Power, Reinhard Bendix and Seymour M. Lipset (eds.) (Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1953), pp. 388-95. 31 on entrepreneurship as a role, and on the orientation and behavior of the man who assumes this role. Cole's definition differs from both Knight's and Schumpeter's. He says: Entrepreneurship may be defined as the purposeful activity (including an integrated sequence of decisions) of an individual or group of associated individuals, undertaken to initiate, maintain, or aggrandize a profit-oriented business unit for the production or distribution of economic goods and services with pecuniary or other advantage of the goal or measure of success, in interaction (or within the conditions established by) the inter- nal situation of the unit itself or with the eco- nomic, political, and social circumstances (insti- tutions and practices) of a period which allows an appreciable measure of freedom of decision.6 With this approach it is possible to focus on the initia- ting, maintaining, and aggrandizing of a business organi- zation. In this way, it moves away from the risk-bearing behavior as the major focus of research. The consideration here focuses on the individual who establishes a business and what is required of him to maintain successful oper— ation and growth of his business. Entrepreneurship in Agriculture In his review of entrepreneurship in relation to agriculture, Danhof suggests that recognition of entre— preneurship as an activity or a function, not as a spe- cific individual or occupation, allows the individual to 6Arthur H. Cole, "Entrepreneurship and Entrepreneur- ial History: The Institutional Setting," Change and the Entrepreneur (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 19H9), p. 88. 32 engage in the activity frequently, occasionally, very rarely, or never.7 In this way it may be said that the individual is characterized by the activity of an entre- preneurial nature. Danhof agrees with other writers cited above that the entrepreneur as characterized in much of the writing of economic theorists is an unrealistic abstraction. Many times management and entrepreneurial activity are defined as being one and the same. However, Danhof makes the distinction that management deals with an inte- grated series of decisions that do not necessarily change the formula of production while entrepreneurial activity is primarily concerned with changes in the formula. Con- sequently, the element of change is important in this context. Specifically, Danhof points out: The determination of the formula whereby economic production is to be carried out at any given time within a specific environment (geographical, intel- lectual, within a particular political and sogial milieu) is then the entrepreneurial function. He suggests the breakdown of the functions of an entre- preneur into three major categories: (1) obtaining infor- mation of a relevant character; (2) evaluation of the 7Clarence H. Danhof, "Observations on Entrepreneur- ship in Agriculture," Change and the Entrepreneur (Cam— bridge: Harvard University Press, 19A9), pp. 20-2“. 8Ibid., p. 22. 33 information from the point of view of profit; and (3) action which determines the use of resources. Danhof continues: The action is rational; hence it is based in so far as possible on evaluated information. Once a deci- sion has been made as to what kind of information is wanted and from what point of view it is to be evaluated, such functions may be delegated--may in fact be institutionalized. But the initiative which sets such operations in motion is entrepreneurial. Moreover, almost always judgment must be employed as a substitute for information or inconclusive analysis. The results of such action are the res- ponsibilitg of the entrepreneur and cannot be delegated. Within the framework of agriculture Danhof assumes that an operation is entrepreneurial in character if the individual takes action in which the results are dependent upon his analysis of production, the market, and other relevant factors, and if he is under no contractual or political obligation to accept advice or direction from anyone. Up to this point, agriculture is noteworthy as one indus- try in which the refusal of a farmer to assume even a minimal level of entrepreneurial activity does not, if he owns or controls the resources he uses, force him out of business. Danhof indicates four types of entrepreneurship which might be found within the agricultural framework: 1. ‘Innovating entrepreneurship, characterized by aggressive assemblage of information and analysis of results from novel combinations of factors. 9Danhof, p. 22. 3A 2. Imitative entrepreneurship, characterized by readiness to adopt successful innovations inaugurated by innovating entrepreneurs. 3. "Fabian" entrepreneurship, characterized by very great caution and skepticism (perhaps simply inertia) but which does not initate when it becomes perfectly clear that failure to do so would result in a loss of the rela— tive position of the enterprise. A. Drone entrepreneurship, characterized by a refusal to adOpt opportunities to make changes in production formulae even at the cost of 10 severely reduced returns to other like producers. How is Entrepreneurshipyto be Used in This Study? Following Cole and Danhof, the definition to be applied to the agricultural entrepreneur in this study is: that individual who performs the activipy or function of gathering together the necessary resources to initiate, maintain, or aggrandize the farm firm. Since all of the farm firms in this study are past the initiation stage, we will be concerned primarily with their maintenance and aggrandizment. Aggrandizment will be viewed here as not only en- largement of the sphere of influence of the firm but also as its adaptation to meet the needs of the changing social structure within which it functions. Maintenance will be viewed as that effort required for the farm firm to con- tinue in operation, but not necessarily as that of being a viable, dynamic firm. loDanhof, pp. 23-24. 35 The Nature and Utility of Constructed Types In looking at farm firms, the influence of the owner (manager) upon these firms has been given very little 'attention. Granted, farm management theory is based upon the economic decisions that can be made by the farmer (manager) but this body of theory is predicated on ration— ality, and man does not always act in an economically rational manner. There is a great spread in the ways one might anticipate the logical response of a farmer and his firm to a given situation and the ways in which he objec- tively does respond. This narrower range of objective responses may be viewed in terms of a continuum consisting of two polar types with all possible shades of gradation between. McKinney has developed the tool of constructive typology which will be utilized in this study for the development of polar types. His definition of construc- tive typology is "a purposive, planned selection, abstrac- tion, combination, and (sometimes) accentuation of a set of criteria with empirical referents that serves as a basis of empirical cases." McKinney says the constructed type is a heuristic device developed primarily for com- parative and predictive purposes rather than to provide the basis for description of situations.11 llMcKinney, pp. 3—6. 36 The basis for generalization within science is through the development of concepts. Concepts, as such, are the result of categorizing recurring experience (in the case of the social sciences, human experience). When the scientist begins to analyze and classify his data, he is moving away from reality at the perceptual level and is beginning to formalize and order, or categorize, the recurring experiences at a more general level. As this process continues, the categorization of recurring exper- iences takes in larger portions of that experience as con- cepts become specified and, as such, the concepts are at a more general level than real experience and will always remain as hypothetical representations of reality. McKin- ney points out that "concepts are constructs, even when 12 they closely reflect perceptual experience." In the way that concepts are given precision through selection and limitation, constructed types are given the same level of precision through selection, limitation, combination, and accentuation. Unique to the constructed type is that: The constructed type organizes experience in a somewhat different fashion than does the ordinary concept in that it forms a series of attributes into a configuration that is not necessarily directly experienced and accentuates one or more of the attributes for theoretical purposes.l l2McKinney, p. 11. 13Ibid. 37 Thus, the constructed type is a heuristic device that is a configuration of attributes not directly experienced in the world in the form in which they are found in the con- structed type. It is useful as a basis for comparing and understanding the empirical world. One of the major areas of criticism of any typology, whether it be "Ideal" as in the sense of Weber's bureau- cratic typology or Redfield's folk-urban typology, is that too often the users of these typologies tend to reify them. When a set of characteristics has been abstracted from reality and formulated into a type, too often the users forget that the type is merely a tool for ordering con- crete phenomena and not something which can represent the real or the empirical world. Consequently, the scientific value of the constructed type is the use to which it is put. There are many things which the constructed type cannot do and a clear recogni- tion of these limitations is essential. The major function of all types is to identify and simplify, whether they have been empirically or more impressionistically constructed. The major utility of the constructed type is that it "per- forms the task of guiding the initial selection of data in "1“ terms of the schema of a given science. One of the many ways in which the constructed type may be used is as a way l“McKinney, p. 18. 38 of interpreting a particular situation or situations. In this way it functions as a general standard to which con- crete occurrence may be compared. Another way in which the constructed type may be used is that of a generalizing concept which will provide the basis for extraction of empirical versions from different cultural contexts. The Constructed Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Types ' In the following two sections the major attributes of the constructed types will be defined as the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farm Firm and the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Firm. It must be pointed out that the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm is headed by a man who assumes the role of entre- preneur. It is the orientation and behavior of this man and his effect on the farm firm that is our concern here. Since the entrepreneurial role is only one of the roles assumed by the above mentioned individual, we also will be concerned with the orientation of the individual that underlies not only this but other roles assumed by him. Orientation is used here in the same sense as used by Merton: A word of explanation is needed for this concept of orientation. The social orientation differs from the social role. Role refers to the manner in which the rights and duties inherent in a social position are put into practice; orientation, as here conceived, refers to the theme underlying the complex of social roles performed by an indi- vidual. It is the (tacit or explicit) theme which 39 finds expression in each of the complex of social roles in which the individual is implicated.1 Merton uses this concept of orientation in discussing what he calls "types of influentials." He constructs two types of influentials, local and cosmopolitan. The chief criterion for distinguishing the two is found in their orieppation toward Rovere. The localite largely confines his interest to this community. Rovere is essentially his world. De- voting little thought or energy to the Great Society, he is preoccupied with local problems, to the vir- tual exclusion of the national and international scene. He is, strictly speaking, parochial. Contrariwise with the cosmopolitan type. He has some interest in Rovere and must of course main— tain a minimum of relations within the community since he, too, exerts influence there. But he is also oriented significantly to the world outside Rovere, and regards himself as an integral part of the world. He resides in Rovere but lives in the» Great Society. If the local type is parochial, the cosmopolitan is ecumenical. There is a great deal of similarity between Merton's types of influentials and the types of individuals who are asso- ciated with the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farm Firms and Adap- tive Entrepreneurial Farm Firms to be considered in this study. We also find a great deal of similarity between the two extreme types of agricultural entrepreneurship iden- tified by Danhof, those of "Drone Entrepreneurship" which resemble those firms headed by Rigid Entrepreneurial 15Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social Struc- ture (Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1956), p. 392. 16Ibid., p. 393. A0 Farmers and the "Innovating Entrepreneurship" which resem- ble those firms headed by our Adaptive Farmers.l7 The constructed types will be presented in outline form. The major focus will be upon the social partici— pation of the entrepreneur, his farm management, his labor management, and a look at his farm as a firm. Quotations from the raw data will be utilized for illustrative pur- poses only. They are meant only to help the reader better understand the typology and its elements as it is presented. Rigid Entrepreneurial Farm Firms A. Social Participation As indicated above, the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer would be a "localite" using Merton's terminology and might be characterized as a "Drone Entrepreneur" in Danhof's terminology. In both of these cases the individual with these characteristics who assumes the entrepreneurial role centers his attention on the immediate, the present. He does not tend to look to the future or necessarily make plans to adapt his firm to the needs or demands of the future. He may be aware that there are organizations and agencies that may be available to lend assistance to him in dealing with the problems of his firm, but due to his concern with the present he will place a high level of reliance on his individual abilities rather than relying l7Danhof, pp. 23-2A. Al on the guidance of others in these organizations and agen- cies that might help him to adjust his firm to the-needs of the future. 1. Member of a Farm Organization The Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer is not a member of one of the general farm organizations.'~ He does not see that membership in one of these organizations will have any immediate benefit for him. Since the prime objective of these organizations is to create pressure on various governmental agencies to develOp policies and legislation favorable to the farmer and agricultural industry, he sees this as being something for the future. He does not feel that there would be any immediate pay—off for him and, consequently, cannot justify his membership in one of these organizations. 2. Member of Fraternal or Social Organization Our Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer does not belong to any social or fraternal organizations. Since he places a high value on self-reliance, he cannot see how his member- ship and participation in any of these organizations will benefit him or his firm. He would see that the time he would need to invest in these organizations would be at the expense of his firm and he does not perceive that the inter-personal contacts with members of these organizations can in any way benefit his firm. He would look upon them as frivolous and as something that would take his energies A2 from something he perceives to be more important, his undivided attention to his firm. 3. Member of Michigan Horticultural Society, Commodity Organization, or Cooperative These specific organizations will not find the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer on their membership roster. As with general farm organizations and social or fraternal organizations, he feels that these organizations can be of no benefit to him. The Michigan Horticultural Society may be perceived as being two-pronged in its influence: a) that of exerting pressure on various governmental agen- cies to bring about legislation and policies favorable to horticultural farm enterprises in ways similar to those practiced by general farm organizations; and b) that of being a conveyor of new knowledge and technology that will benefit farmers who operate horticultural enterprises. The commodity organizations and various cooperatives extend the influence of the individual farmer into the market place or to the source of agricultural supplies, and through the pressure of numbers attempt to cause favorable treatment for their membership. Again, our Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would not per- ceive these organizations as being of any immediate bene- fit to him or his firm. He would view them as a tool to usurp some of his own power. Since he places a high value on self-reliance and control of his own destiny, he_would not give up any of his freedom for possible rewards at A3 some future date. He would consider the activities of these organizations as frivolous, with little meaning and not worthy of the investment of his energies and/or resources. B. Ferm Management The Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would be characterized as being extremely conservative in his style of enterprise management. He would be characterized as the operator of a firm that is not articulating to the changes within the production or the marketing sector of the economy. The old adage of "if it was good enough for my father, it's good enough for me" would hold for this individual. The firm would be static in nature, not changing in size and/or scope, and the major portion of the entrepreneur's energy would be expended on the maintenance of the organi- zation with no concern at all for the aggrandizement of the organization. 1. Farm Management Spyle The management style of the Rigid Farmer Entrepre- neur could be said to be static. He is making no effort to adjust the firm to changes in production technology or the changing needs of the market place. His major con- cern is "hanging on" tK>what he now has; he is extremely critical of others who are making additional investments in their enterprises to articulate more closely to the AA needs of the changing market place. In the words of one of our respondents: I really don't think there's any future in fruit farming in this area. The processors are dic— tating our prices and the town people are raising our taxes with their fancy new schools. I've got some land I could plant to new trees, but what's the use--the processor won't pay me a decent price ‘for the fruit and those new trees will just raise my taxes. If I can just hang on for a few years more Ma and I are going to retire and sell the farm--let somebody else worry about paying the taxes then. 2. Adoption of Innovations Following from the static farm management style, the Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur will adopt innovations only as a last resort in an effort to maintain his present enterprise at its existing level, or some lower level which he still finds tolerable. As pointed out earlier, the Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would represent Danhof's "Drone Entrepreneur." It will be remembered that Danhof characterized the Drone Entrepreneur by "a refusal to adopt opportunities to make changes in production formulae even at the cost of severely reduced returns to other like "18 Consequently, the Rigid Farmer Entrepre- producers. neur will pass up the opportunity to adopt new varieties which might be more desirable in the market place or might lend themselves to mechanical harvest; he will not adopt new and/or improved chemicals which might improve the quality of his product or lower production costs; he will not purchase new and/or different machinery which might l8Danhof, p. 2A A5 make his operation more efficient; and he will not adopt new harvest techniques, be they mechanical or different hand harvest methods which might make his produce more acceptable in the market place. He may not absolutely refuse to adopt any of these innovations, but he may adopt limited numbers of them under protest in an effort to maintain his organization at its present or at a lower tolerable level of return. One of our respondents expressed his views as follows: A lot of growers are planting those new dwarf apple trees 'cause they are supposed to come into production earlier and make more money. But I just can't see 'em--they ain't natural. A apple tree's got to be big to grow a lot of apples, those little dwarfs just ain't gonna do the job. Besides, apples was meant to be picked from a ladder, not just standing on the ground! 3. Contact with Knowledge Sources The state Land Grant University and its various appendages are generally considered to be a knowledge source in regard to production and marketing knowledge for agricultural producers. Granted, there are also many commercial and mass media sources for this information, but in general the sources available through the Land Grant University are considered to be reliable and the information available is considered to be current. Two specific appendages to the Land Grand University that are of special importance to the farmer are the COOpera- tive Extension Service and the Agricultural Experiment Station. A6 For the horticultural specialty crop farmer, the Agricultural Experiment Station is of special importance in that there are regional experimental farms located in the horticultural specialty crop areas of the state where research is carried on that is especially relevant to that limited geographical area. Through direct contact with university-based researchers at these variOus experi- mental farms, especially at the annual "Field Days," the Farmer Entrepreneur is able to garner current research information which may be of direct benefit to him in his own enterprise. The COOperative Extension Service, through its net- work of locally-based agricultural agents, offers a direct knowledge source or a liaison to the knowledge source based at the university that may benefit the grower by solving existing problems or adjusting his enterprise to the future needs of the market place. The Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would not look to these appendages of the Land Grant University as legitimate knowledge sources for a number of reasons and would tend to rely upon his own judgment in making adjustments in his own enterprise to maintain it at a minimally viable level. A. Feelings about Gropp Bargaining for Better Prices The Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would not participate in any group efforts to obtain a better or more stable price for his commodities. He would look to the groups or organizations which are attempting to do this as A7 infringements upon his own ability to market his produce as well as the free enterprise system of the country. It is his feeling that supply and demand always will dictate the market conditions. He would refuse to join a bargaining group or organization, even if it meant that he would lose his existing market outlet; rather than doing this he would seek a new or alternative outlet for his produce. In an extreme example, one respondent stated: We have come this far on the free enterprise system, and if it hasn't been good this far, something is definitely wrong. And this is what I can't understand. Some of the larger growers, I'm a very small grower, but some Of the larger growers in the area that I can rem- ember that started out smaller than actually I am, and have got up to the hundreds of acres of fruit, and have come a long ways in the free enterprise system, and now they are all for gov- ernment controls, and you can't understand what happened to them. I mean, they, if they would have had government controls, they'd never be where they are today. But still this is what they're after, and I can't understand their thinking. 5. Feelings about Worker Unionization The Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur is adamant in his opposition to unionization by agricultural workers. He would either change his enterprise so that it could be totally mechanized or would cease to Operate rather than deal with unionized agricultural labor. Again, he feels that this would be an infringement upon his autonomy and would oppose this infringement with the only tools he has, those Of his enterprise-—which he would modify so that it did not require additional labor-— A8 or he would retreat entirely and cease to operate. The views Of one respondent are: I have never been for unions. Unions have their place, but they have definitely overstepped their bounds in industry. They will do the same in agriculture. We have no way of stopping them. Our way of life says that everybody is entitled to their own freedom of worship and anything else, and the union can be considered this. Now, when it gets to the point where the union tells the owners how to run their business, then to me they have gone too far. True, we need workers, but they need employment--but to say labor should rule and run the business, this is out. If agricultural labor unionizes and it gets to the point where I cannot manage it or handle it, both physically or cost-wise, because it is definitely continually getting higher priced, and other, or such as workmens comp and so forth going on, social security rates going up, to the point where our commodities will not pay for it. I still have a bulldozer, the trees will come out, I can go into crops that can be harvested with machines. C. Labor Management The Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur would be characterized as being very conservative and traditional in his labor management style. Since he places a high level or reli- ance upon his own abilities, he is unwilling to share decision-making or the supervision of labor with anyone else. He does not feel that anyone else can do the job the way he would want it done. He will place himself at a location in the organization Of the work flow so that he can exert maximum direct control over all phases of the operation but specifically he will place himself so that he has direct control over employees. He will directly make corrections of mistakes and/or errors made A9 by the employees rather than have an intermediary assume this responsibility. Because of his present time orien- tation, he will not plan ahead for his labor needs and will not contact his harvest crew prior to the time of the harvest. He may also be said to be extremely pater— nalistic in his relations with his employees. He will treat them as if they were children and do not have the ability to make decisions concerning their own course of action. Following from this, he will be extremely hostile towards individuals or groups of employees who do not adhere to his dictates in regard to their personal con— duct and he will Openly resent any attempt towards inde- pendence shown by their employees. 1. Location of the Farmer durinngarvest The physical location of the farmer during the har— vest Operation is one that must be appropriately con- sidered. The Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer would locate himself directly at the scene of the harvest. He would assume the supervision Of the harvest crew, even though he may have already retained someone, such as a crew leader, whom he is technically paying to supervise the harvest crew. He is not willing to relinquish this portion of responsibility and authority to anyone else since he is unwilling to trust anyone but himself. He also feels responsible for correcting any mistakes or errors the 50 harvest crew makes while it is picking. He is not willing to go through an intermediary, such as another family member, full—time employee, or the crew leader, but feels that it is his responsibility to correct the error. One respondent put it this way: I just can't trust anybody else out in the field. The pickers would ruin me if I weren't on top of them all the time. I put in nearly a whole year getting the crop ready for harvest and they could put me out of business in a few days if they didn't pick the stuff right. There is a leader that comes here with the crew, and I pay him a good wage, but he don't watch the quality like I want it done. The only way I can get what I want is to be out there in the field checking on the pickers myself. 2. Chain of Command Due to his lack Of trust of others, the Rigid Entre- preneurial Farmer does not develop a chain of command, even though he may have others in his employ who are cap- able of participating in a chain of command. As charac- terized earlier in this presentation, he is unwilling to share his autonomy and authority with anyone. He will not divest himself of any of the responsibility for giving orders, such as sharing this with other family members, full-time employees, or a crew leader who may be in his employ. He will tend not to hire a crew with a crew leader since this would pose a threat to his absolute line of authority and he definitely is not willing to share decision—making in relation to the firm with any- one else. 51 He considers himself to be totally self-sufficient with regard to making all decisions about his firm; he assumes total responsibility for issuing any orders and/or instructions that he deems necessary. The response of one respondent summed up this attitude: It's my farm and nobody's going to run it but me. I just can't trust nobody else to boss the crew, as soon as you give them a inch they take a mile--pretty soon you can't even run your own farm anymore! 3. Relationship with Migrant Crew Since our Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer tends not to hire crews to harvest his crops but rather hires individ— uals or families that may come to him, he will have a high labor turn-over from year to year. Also, because of his lack of willingness to share decision-making and super- vision with others and his direct involvement in the cor- rection of mistakes or errors, he is likely to have a negative effect on his employees' satisfaction in working for him. We also will find that the Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur does not plan ahead and, consequently, is content to recruit his harvest crew during the harvest season. He is not willing to make commitments ahead of time to poten- tial employees so he does not contact any of his poten— tial migrant workers during the winter. He feels that those workers who were happy in working for him will return of their own accord and any contact he might make 52 with those workers who had performed satisfactorily for him the previous year would be forcing him to make a com- mitment that he is unwilling to make. The response of one respondent to the question of how he obtained his har- vest help was: "I just pick them up wherever I can get them whether they're migrant labor or what." Another respondent stated: "I just go downtown--you'll always see somebody walking around looking for work. This way I don't owe anybody anything--If they want to work I got a job for them, if they don't, I'll look some more.". A. Decisions in Regard to Migrant or Seasonal Labor As pointed out above, the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer does not plan ahead as a matter of principle. He is unwilling to make a commitment to labor ahead of time since he is unsure of crop conditions and is afraid of the obligations with which he will be faced if he should have a larger crew than he requires when the harvest time arrives. Consequently, he will generally respond to the question "When do you determine the amount of labor needed for the upcoming season?" by saying, "When I see how big the crop will be!" For the recruitment of his harvest crew he depends entirely upon personal contact with mi- grants, usually at some local community center, or upon those who might stop at the farm asking for work. He ignores the established State Employment Service and does not make prior contact with workers who have performed satisfactorily for him in the past. 53 He feels that those workers who like him as a person will come back to him another year and that there is nothing that he can do to make working for him more attrac- tive than working for someone else. A reflection of this may be seen in his attitude toward wages. His general response here might be that "If I pay as well or better than the next man, I'll have all the crew I need." He does not perceive improved working or housing conditions nor improved fringe benefits such as hospitalization insur— ance as being of any benefit to him in recruiting or re- taining a crew. 5. EmployeefRelations The Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer tends to be pater- nalistic in his relations with his employees. He treats his employees as if they might be part of his family. He feels that they are somewhat childlike or immature and should be treated accordingly. He is concerned about guiding them along the "right" path and may see himself as a father-figure to his workers and thus he has to pro- tect them from the temptations of the outside world. He is generally critical of the way his employees spend their money and Often will comment on their "continual trading in junk cars" or the fact that they are always broke the day after payday and have to come to him for ad. advance to buy groceries. He is not willing to share decision-making about his enterprise with anyone, nor is he willing to share 5A supervision responsibility. Likewise, it may be said that he would like to assume the responsibility for the indi— vidual conduct of his workers and feels deeply hurt when they do not respond to his proffered guidance and counsel. One respondent put it this way: The minute they get here they are chasing after you--They come knocking at your door wanting to borrow a dollar, a dozen eggs, or a loaf of bread. We pay off the crew on Friday night and Sunday morning the parade starts in--a loaf of bread, a pound of hamburg, a dozen eggs--they just can't handle money. Or, as put by another respondent: I told them they could make more money here and have a free house and everything, but they just wouldn't listen, they moved on. They just don't seem to have no sense. D. The Farm as a Firm The firm of the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer is the result of his Farm Management Style and his contact with the larger community. Consequently, if his farm manage- ment style can be characterized as being static, so can the firm. The firm will be stable or declining in size; there will be no plans to make new plantings or switch to more acceptable varieties; there will be no plans to pur- chase new or improved equipment and the Rigid Entrepre— neurial Farmer will not be planning for the future by his involvement in bargaining organizations or other groups that might enhance his position in the market place. This type Of firm can best be illustrated by the statement of one of our respondents: 55 To me, farming is a way of life. I don't have no truck with all those organizations that want you to join to make farming better. My place is big enough for me and I get by. Some years I make out better than others, but then with the weather and the market the way it is, you can't expect to have a good year every year. A lot of my neighbors have gone out and borrowed money to buy new machinery, or plant new orchards, but not me. I just can't see going into debt for anything with the future so uncertain. No sir, I'll hang on and get by. Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Firms In this section we will deal with the second Of the constructed types in this study, that of the Adaptive Entre- preneurial Farm Firm. The Rigid Entrepreneurial Farm Firm discussed in the last section and the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Firm to be discussed in this section represent polar types. It must be remembered that these polar types do not exist in reality but are heuristic devices only and their utility may be found in the development of a better under- standing of empirical reality. All cases included in this study will deviate from these constructed polar types, but their placement on the Rigid-Adaptive continuum (to be dis— cussed in Chapter III) will aid in understanding the be- havior of the Farmer Entrepreneur and his relationships with his employees. A. Social Participation While the Rigid Entrepreneurial Farmer was charac- terized as being a "localite" in Mertonian terminology, the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer may be characterized as being "Cosmopolitan" in character. The individual who assumes this latter entrepreneurial role may be said to 56 be future-oriented and concerned with happenings beyond his own locality. He realizes that decisions made in other parts of the country or the world will have a direct effect upon him as well as his enterprise. He is willing to give his energy, resources, and abilities in an attempt to favorably influence decisions that may affect his firm. He is a joiner in the best American tradition and looks to organizations as the vehicle for multiplying his influence upon the larger world. 1. Member of a Farm Organization Our Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer will be a member of at least one of the general farm organizations, and he may well be an officer at the local, regional, state, or national level. He looks to the general farm organization as a vehicle for making his wants and desires known in the places where policy decisions might be made that would affect his enterprise or where legislation affecting his enterprise is being enacted. Henwy participate in and reap some benefit from the many services that are offered by the general farm organi- zations today, but his prime purpose for membership is to provide a pipeline to the seats of power that might affect his enterprise. He will tend to downgrade the "fringe benefits" offered by the general farm organizations since he will shop for these goods and services in the market I place and purchase them where he can gain the greatest 57 advantage. This might be from the general farm organi— zation or it might be from some other commercial source. 2. Member of Fraternal or Social Organization The Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer will continue his "joiner" tradition by being a member of one or more social or fraternal organizations. He will regard these organizations as providing contacts that may make it pos- sible for him to enhance his business enterprise, both locally and within the larger geographical sphere. These organizations also supply an opportunity to perform pub- lic service which he sees as his responsibility. He will view his investment of time and energy in these organizations as an investment in his enterprise, since he will be seeking ways to maximize the benefits from the contacts that he makes through these organizations. 3. Member of Michigan Horticultural Society, Commodity Organization, or COOperative The Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer definitely will be a member of these organizations. He looks to the Michigan Horticultural Society both as a knowledge source and as a pressure group that is constituted to enhance his own specific interest and feels that his participation in this organization is vital to not only the welfare of his individual firm but to all horticultural enterprises in Michigan. In addition, he will be an active member of any commodity organization that represents crOps he is raising 58 and will regard it as a vehicle for enhancing the market for his produce, influencing prices, and/or creating a more favorable public image for his particular crop. He will view his membership in various cooperatives in many of the same ways, if they are constituted to market a crop or bargain with processors for prices. ‘In addition, if the cooperative purchases goods or supplies, he will con- sider it as one source when deciding where to purchase the goods and supplies required in his enterprise. In discus- sing his involvement in commodity organizations, one res- pondent states: It is high time that we as growers combine our efforts through commodity or bargaining organi- zations if we are going to be able to get an equitable return for our produce. I have been involved in commodity organizations that bargain with processors for the crops I raise since their very beginning, in fact I have served on the board of directors of one of these organizations for the past several years. I feel that if I am ever going to get better treatment in the market, it is up to me to help do something about it. By working through commodity organizations I see that we as producers are able to control enough of the production of a particular commodity so that we can bargain realistically with processors. B. Farm Management. The Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer may be charac- terized as being very innovative in his farm management style. In Danhof's terminology, he could be character- ized as being an "Innovative Entrepreneur." It will be remembered that Danhof defined this type of entrepreneur as one who is "characterized by aggressive assemblage of 59 information and analysis of results from novel combinations of factors."19 He may be characterized as the operator of a firm who is not only articulating to the changing needs of the market place but one who is anticipating these changes and attempting to organize his enterprise so that he might capitalize upon them. He would be the individual who would be operating in the futures market for the com- modities he raises, if such a market existed. He is the individual who would be beating on the doors of academic as well as commercial researchers to ferret out production technology and cultural practice information that might benefit his enterprise before it becomes general public knowledge. He is the type of individual who would be willing to capitalize his enterprise so that he would be in a position to take advantage of perceived and predicted changes within the production and/or market system. 1. Farm Management Style The management style of this individual could be best characterized as "dynamic," one that is changing con- tinually with the changing demands of the market place as well as with production technology. It is the style of management as concerned about next year, or five years from now, as it is with today. The Adaptive Entrepre- neurial Farmer continually is re-evaluating his position and making changes in his enterprise that will allow him 19Danhof, p. 23. 60 to be competitive at some future time. The story of one of the respondents in this study illustrates this perspec- tive on management. The respondent said: We have been replanting to dwarf apple stock so that we can cut down on labor requirements. By planting in hedge-rows we not only get more trees per acre, but cut down on our pruning and spraying labor and will all but eliminate additional labor at harvest time. Also, we have gotten into the fancy apple trade. We used to market most of our crop through proces- sors or over the auction, but a few years ago we decided that we should capitalize on the good quality of our fruit. We have built up a trade that now takes most of our crop as fancy apples, and what's more--we don't wait until the crop is harvested to sell it-—we have signed contracts at a specified deliVered price six months prior to harvest time. 2. Adoption of Innovations The Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur is not only the "Early Adopter" of innovations; in many instances he is .the "creator of innovations." Through his future orien- tation and his intimate knowledge of both the production and market systems that relate to his type of enterprise, he may be able to predict needed changes required to keep his enterprise in a competitive position or give it some advantage over others. Through this knowledge he will be better equipped to anticipate needed changes in his own operation and, consequently, may take.it upon himself to create the innovation required to place his operation in the desired position, or he may employ someone to create the innovation for him. He will look to innovations in 61 not only production technology but to changes in the organ- izational structure of his enterprise as well. He may even go so far as to create a market system that will be able to capitalize upon some unique characteristic of his own enterprise. 3. Contact with Knowledge Sources The Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur will avail himself of all public or private knowledge sources. In the public sphere, he will develop close contact with university-based researchers who deal with the problems of his enterprise not only at the Land Grant University in his own state but in other states where similar work also is being done. He will have direct contact with many of the key researchers and he will have the ability to translate their research findings directly into formulae for application to his own enterprise. Rather than looking to the Cooperative Extension Staff for direct service, he probably will look to them as a liaison group which has the ability to Open doors to researchers and others at the Land Grant University who could benefit him directly. He will develop a close per- sonal relationship with Cooperative Extension Personnel since he views this relationship as one which will be able to benefit his enterprise at some future date. It is this type of agricultural entrepreneur who will pro- vide pressure on the university-based researcher to 62 investigate some problem that might be specific to his type of enterprise, and in many instances he may also provide or locate the resources to underwrite the costs of this research. As indicated by one respondent: I know that this TelFarm is really a research pro- ject for those Ag Economists up at State, but since I joined the project and got accurate records on my own farm, it sure helped me to clean out some of my dead enterprises. Take peaches for instance. I like to grow peaches and we have always been able to sell them good, but those TelFarm records showed that those peaches were stealing me blind--so this spring I jerked them all out and I'm going to re- plant to apples, that's what the Ag Economists up at State as well as those Hort guys down at the Sodus Experiment Station say will be real big for us in this area. A. Feelings about Group Bargaining for Better Prices As indicated by participation and membership in numerous organizations that might have a hand in bar- gaining for better prices for commodities raised by the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer, it is apparent that he is highly in favor of this practice. He will lend his full support to any effort he deems legitimate and will assume leadership in the effort, if required. He per- ceives the long-range benefits of group bargaining as being of special benefit to his enterprise since this will provide him with higher predictability in regard to the future, thus making it possible for him to do more realistic long-range planning. When asked about his reaction to group bargaining for better prices, one respondent said: 63 Well, I certainly think that as a group the growers need someone to bargain for them. As individuals it's useless to try to bargain with the processors. I think that's a lesson that we've seemed not to learn, but I think it's essential that we have an organization to represent us at the bargaining table. In addition to his feelings about the essentialness of group bargaining, the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer is the type of individual who would be capable of initiating a movement to form a bargaining organization if there were none already in existence, or he might be the person to lead a movement to force a presently existing but ineffectual bargaining organization to change it policies and/or personnel so that it might be more effective. 5. Feelings about Worker Unionization The Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur is looking forward to the unionization of agricultural workers since this will give him a more structured situation within which to work. He perceives the Union organization as assuming some of the responsibility for employees that he now has, and he is willing to pay for this. He feels that it will make his enterprise a more efficient one, one that can be more flexible, if he is able to unload some of his pres- ent responsibilities. He sees the union as providing the means to formalize wage and grievance procedures with employees, thus providing him with more predictable, structured situations with which he can deal rather than the individualistic, erratic situation which exists in most loose-knit organizations, such as farms. 6A If big labor comes around and wants to organize farm workers and stand behind the organization, I'm gonna say-~let's sit down and get this thing started. But, if church groups or other such outfits come around who don't represent the working man, there's gonna be trouble. With the union standing behind the workers I can sit down with their bargaining agent, talk to their stewards and whatnot and I can tell me just what it's gonna cost me to bring a crop in. Now I'll have to guarantee so much, but the union will have to guarantee me a crew. With this kind of guarantee and knowing what my costs are gonna be, I can deal with the processor in a more realistic manner and be able to predict if I will be able to eat steak next winter, or if it's gonna be another winter of beans. C. Labor Management The Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur may be character- ized as being very liberal and progressive in his labor management style. He will utilize every opportunity to involve the employees in relevant decisions and will create a climate in which the employees will feel free to express feelings in regard to the work situation. He will have established a hierarchial chain of command and this chain of command will be well understood by the workers. He will expect workers to take grievances and suggestions to the proper person in the chain of com- mand, but he also will be open to direct suggestions from the workers themselves. He will not be directly responsible for training workers and/or correcting mistakes that they make but will have delegated this responsibility, along with appropriate authority, to someone else in his employ. 65 Since he is future oriented he will begin making plans for securing a harvest crew very early. He will make contact with desirable crews or individuals during the winter to make certain they will be on his farm when harvest time arrives. In addition to informal contact with these workers, he will rely upon the services of the relevant State Employment Services to formalize his con- tract with the employees. His style of labor management may be characterized as open, that is, democratic, bar- gaining, and rational. He will consider the employees as individuals and respect their human dignity. He will be open to their suggestions and comments and will attempt to create the most desirable working conditions possible within the limits of the situation placed upon him by external forces. 1. Location of the Farmer during Harvest The Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer will spend a limited amount of time in the field during the harvest. He will not supervise the crew directly nor assume direct responsibility for correcting mistakes made by the harvest crew. He will place himself in some other position that will allow him more flexibility in dealing with the total enterprise. He could not justify expending all of his energy on just one phase of the enterprise while his attention is required on numerous other phases at the same time. One respondent put it this way: 66 I've got to be flexible. I try to spend as much time at the phone during harvest season as I can, because that's how I do my selling. But when I leave to run out to see how the harvest crew is coming, check on things down at the packing shed, or chase down some repair parts, I'm always in contact with the home base with my CB radio-—I've got to keep in constant touch with all phases of the Operation so that the crew leader with the harvest crew, the foreman of the packing shed, or my spray man can have their crew doing what is going to be making the most money for all of us. 2. Chain of Command A chain of command definitely would be present on the farm operation of the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer. Even if the enterprise is quite small, he will set up some hierarchy so that he will not be required to make "all" decisions. He feels that it is not only to his own benefit to share decision-making with others, but it also enhances their position and ego-satisfaction, thereby creating a tighter-knit work force. If the operation or harvest crew is of sufficient size, he will hire a foreman or, more likely, a crew with a crew leader to harvest his crops. He will deal speci- fically with the foreman or crew leader in relation to problems of the harvest and will not have any direct con- tact of a supervisory nature with members Of the harvest crew. 3. Relationship with Migrant Crew Because of his policy of shared decision-making, the work climate on the farm of the Adaptive Entrepre- neurial Farmer is likely to be such that employees find 67 it a desirable place to work. Consequently, there will be a high rate of return each year among the members of the migrant crews. Another factor leading to this high rate of return is the fact that our Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer uses all available means of maintaining contact with his desirable individuals and crews throughout the year. He will contact them not only by mail or phone periodically during the winter but also will utilize the formalized channels of the various State Employment Serv- ices to maintain his contact. Although he may be reluctant to advance money for transportation or other reasons, he will generally do so to insure the return of desirable crews each year. One respondent said: I kid around a lot with the crew. I ask "do you think that we should pick this block or that block of tomatoes--do you think the melons are ready yet?" This gives the crew the feeling that they have some say in where they work. Then, too, we write back and forth all winter, some- times on my way to Florida in the winter I'll stop Off and visit with some of them. You know--those people in my crew are the sons, daughters, and other kin of the crew that started coming to work for me 20 years ago. A. Decisions in Regard to Migrant or Seasonal Labor Because of the future orientation of the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer he will determine his harvest labor needs early in the winter and make contact with the crews he found desirable the previous season. He will utilize all channels available to him to assure him an adequate 68 supply of labor for the upcoming season. As pointed out above, he will utilize the services of the relevant State Employment Services along with more personal forms of contact, such as phone or mail, and in some instances he may even personally visit the prospective workers at their winter residence. He will avail himself of all possible opportunities to make working for him and his firm a desirable experience so that favored employees will return year after year. He will provide fringe benefits in the form of various insurance programs that are not generally provided to other agricul— tural workers; he will provide housing that is above aver— age; he will provide other amenities such as recreation facilities near the housing area; and, most of all, he will relate to the workers in a way that conveys his concern and interest in them as people. 5. Employee Relations While the Rigid Farmer Entrepreneur could be charac- terized as being paternalistic in his relations with employees, the Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur might be char— acterized as being open (rational, democratic, bargaining) in his relations with employees. He treats them as indi- viduals and respects their individual dignity and is open to discuss working conditions, wages, and other problems which the employee might be having with the job. Because of his belief in sharing decision-making with others and 69 his established chain of command, there is opportunity for employees to feel that they have a stake in the busi- ness and may tend to be more open, realistic, and honest in their dealings with the Farmer Entrepreneur. Because of his concern for his employees, he will be active in creating a climate in his community that will not be hostile to the seasonal workers who come to his farm and he also will utilize his influence to have special services that might be required by these employees made available at the community level. An indication of one approach to bargaining utilized by one grower is: I used to always have pickers grumbling about the pay. Then about three years ago I got together with this crew leader and said "I'm willing to pay a fair wage and pay as much as the next man, but how can we stop the grumbling?" Well we talked it over and came up with this idea of a guaranteed price for each unit picked, and then if the price for picking went above this during the season in the community my pickers would be paid this dif- ference above their minimum guarantee and it would be retroactive to the first lug they pick. Haven't had any grumbling about pay since. D. The Farm as a Firm The Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Frim will be a reflection of the managememt style and orientation to the larger world of the Farmer Entrepreneur. The firm might be characterized as being "dynamic," that is, adjusting to the changes that are required to not only maintain the firm but aggrandize it as well. Through the future orientation of the Adaptive LEntrepreneurial Farmer, the firm continually will be 70 adjusted to meet the projected changes in the market place, to capitalize on new production technology, or to take advantage of new organizational arrangements. For this type Of firm, "change" might well be added to the Old adage of those things that we are sure Of--Death, Taxes, and "Change." The optimism of one of our respondents shows through: Sometimes I can't sleep nights thinking about the future. I get all excited and see this fruit busi- ness as kind of a big game. What is the consumer gonna want, what shape will the processor want it in, what varieties will do best here in my area, where can I get the best rate on a loan . . . It is exciting and so far I have been pretty lucky. I've guessed right more Often than not and so I'm ahead for now. I can see a great future for the fruit business in our part of the country, and you know, the way the population is expanding, they're gonna eat a lot more fruit 5 years from now than they are now. That's why I'm planting every acre I can lay my hands on--I want to be right in the middle of things from here on, not just a hanger on. CHAPTER III THE ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRM CONTINUUM In the development Of the constructed Rigid and Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farm Firms in the last chapter, the unique characteristics of these firms were indicated. There were four major subdivisions to the constructed type: Social Participation, Farm Management, Labor Man- agement, and the Farm as a Firm. Under these four major subdivisions twenty three variables were identified from the data in the larger study. Following the constructed typology, each of the Entrepreneurial Farm Firms included in the study was scored as being either Rigid or Adap- tive on each of the selected variables. The variables and their dichotomization are shown on the following page. The variables on which the farmer or the firm could be characterized as being Rigid were scored as 0 while those variables on which the farmer or the firm might be characterized as being Adaptive were given a score of 1. Following this procedure we would have each farm firm included in the study being assigned a score from 0 to 23. The actual distribution of scores ranged from A to 19. This distribution is presented in Table l. 71 72 Rigid Characteristic Variable Adaptive Characteristic No No No Static Two or less One or none None None No NO Neutral, disfavor, N.R. Neutral, disfavor, N.R. Stays in field to directly supervise harvest Farmer himself 25% or less Workers come to farmer asking for work, processor sup- plies workers, etc. Farmer himself No Liability only May 31 or earlier Loan money or makes monetary advance Paternal Static Social Participation Member of a farm organization Member of a social or fraternal organization Member of Michigan Horticultural Society, Commodity Organization, or Cooperative - Farm Management Farm Management Style Number of pieces purchased in of new machinery last two years Number of new chemicals used in last two years Number Of new plants and seeds used in last two years Number of new harvest techniques used in last two years Contact with MSU Experiment Station with FSU Contact Extension Service Feelings toward group bargaining toward worker unionization Feelings Labor Location of farmer during harvest :‘-;anagez:ient Who corrects picking errors 3 of migrant crew returning each year How does farmer get an adequate supply of labor Who supervises picking (chain of command) Does farmer share decision-making Fringe benefits offered (insurance) When does farmer determine labor needs for upcoming season ‘ What techniques does farmer use to keep workers coming back Employee Relations Farm ae a Firm Farm as a Firm Yes Yes Yes Dynamic Three or more Two or more One or more One or more Yes Yes Favor Favor Is involved in other tasks on or Off farm Someone other than farmer 26% Uses Employ- ment Service, employs a re- cruiter, con- tacts crew leader directly 01" more Someone other than farmer Yes Liability + other forms of insurance June 1 or later Contact during winter, pay better wage, treat right while they are here Open Dynamic 73 TABLE l.--Distribution of 23 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm scores. Score Number of Respondents ’_l [—1 I'\) I—‘ i—‘I—‘WtWI—‘NtNNNONUON-EN 2 II N N Over 50 per cent of the scores cluster between 9 and 12, as might be expected in a normal distribution. Actually, when depicted graphically (Figure l) the distribution tends to show some irregularity which may be attributed to the small sample size. To determine whether each of the 23 variables included in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm score was making an adequate contribution to the total score and to the sub-score of which it is a part (Social Participation-- 3 variables; Farm Management—-9 variables; Labor Management-- 10 variables) each variable was correlated with the total score and with its sub-score. With an N of 77 the 5 per cent level of significance for the coefficient of correlation would be .227 while the 7A 14 IF-qt 13 12 . r 11 10 9 Number 8 of Respond-7 L___J IL._‘ ents I 6 .r_1 5 2 HT 1 2 3 A S 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score Figure l.--Graphic representation of the distrib- ution of the 23 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. 75 l per cent level of significance would be .296. When coefficients of correlation for the 23 variables that make up the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score are reviewed, we find that a number Of them fall below the .227, or 5 per cent, level of significance. They are: Member of a farm organi— zation; Member of a social or fraternal organization; Con- tact with M.S.U. Extension Service; Feelings toward group bargaining; Feeling toward worker unionization; How does the farmer get an adequate supply of labor; Fringe benefits (insurance); and What technique does farmer use to keep workers coming back. However, at a different level of analysis we may view the correlation of each of these variables with its sub- score. The reasoning followed here is that if the variable is highly correlated with its sub-score it will be a strong variable within the total score, even though it may not be as highly correlated to the total score. Therefore, those variables that are not highly correlated with their sub- score (significant at the l per cent level) should be dropped from the total score. Of those variables men- tioned above, all but two meet these criteria: Feelings toward worker unionization, and Fringe benefits (insur- ance). Consequently, these two variables were dropped from the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. The new distribution, then, for the 21 variable score is presented in Table 2. Depicted graphically as 76 in Figure 2 it is interesting to note that the total distri- bution resembles in general that found for the 23 variable score. In both cases it is probably the relatively small N that is responsible for the lack of a more normal distri- bution. It will be noted in Table 3 that where the 23 and the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores are com- pared for each Farm Firm, in no case is there a difference greater than one point between the 23 variable and the 21 variable score. TABLE 2.—-Distribution of 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores. .- —- Score Number of Respondents A 3 5 A 6 l 7 A 8 9 9 9 10 10 ll 7 l2 12 13 5 1A 2 15 3 l6 3 17 A 18 1 N=77 When considering the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score, there are still a number of variables with coefficients of correlation below the .227, the 5 per cent level of significance when the contribution of that variable 14 13 12 ‘F-fi' 11 10 ‘ 9 . Number 8 of Respond-7 ents 6 5 .._., 1 2 3 A 5 6 7 8 9 1O 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score Figure 2.--Graphic representation of the distrib- ution of the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score.' ' 78 TABLE 3.-—1ndividua1 farm firms and their Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores. 23 Variable 21 Variable 23 Variable 21 Variable Farm # Seure Score Farm A Score Score 1 '2 11 A1 16 16 2 17 17 A; 10 15 3 13 1; - A3 lb 16 A 11 11 AA 5 5 5 O :7, I,» 5 5 6 A A An 9 8 7 l 1» 17 B 8 8 IE) I"1 ‘I3 5 8 9 15 , 1A “9 9 9 10 5 A so 9 8 11 11 1 51 13 12 12 12 12 92 A A 13 12 12 93 10 10 l“ 5 2 5A 13 13 15 9 1 Sb 7 7 lo 10 J 56 8 8 17 17 17 57 10 10 18 12 1; 9% 12 11 19 13 13 5; 11 ll 20 2 11 no 1A 1A 21 9 9 t1 lo 10 22 15 15 OZ 19 18 23 lo 16 63 9 9 211 1.: 17'" CHI 9 9 25 10 1O 65 13 13 27 8 7 t7 2 12 28 13 12 68 9 9 29 17 17 69 10 10 3O 10 10 7C 9 9 31 o o 71 11 10 2 ll 10 72 7 7 33 lb 17 73 12 2 3A '2 12 7A 2 12 35 13 13 75 9 9 36 7 7 76 9 8 37 12 2 77 9 8 38 8 8 39 8 8 A0 11 lo 79 to the total score is considered. These variables are the same ones that fell below the .05 per cent level of sig- nificance on the 23 variable score, minus the two variables that were dropped. However, the major change was that in the 21 variable score, the contribution of each variable to the sub-score was generally raised. This comparison may be viewed by an inspection of Table A where the coefficients of correlation for the 23 variable and the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores and their sub-scores are presented. It also must be remembered that these Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores were derived from the operationalization of a Constructed Type. As indicated earlier, the Con- structed Type is a heuristic device and One cannot expect to find it in reality. Consequently, the variation from the normal would be expected, especially in a sample as small as the one utilized for this study. We will recall that McKinney stated that the manifest function of the constructed type is to: identify, simplify, and order the concrete data so that they may be described in terms that make them comparable. . . . In effect, a type consti- tutes a reduction from the complex to the simple; hence the careful construction and use of types, as an intermediate procedure, can potentially make many large—scale problems accessible to more refined methodology and technique. . . . Indeed, a primary role of the constructed type would seem to be that of a sensitizing device. Its use al- lows social scientists cognitively to map broad areas of social phenomena through the systemati- cal tapping of historical and secondary data.1 lMcKinney, p. 216. 8C) TABLE A.--Corre1atlun coefficients for variables in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm score and their c ntributlon to the sub-scores. Entrepreneurial Sub-Score ”arm Firm Score Coefficient Variable Coefficient of of (hirrelzitlon (hyrrelan:ion 23 21 23 21 1,’ .' Y variable Variable Variable Variable fiyuPe Score Score Score SOCIAL PARTICIPATIOL Member of a Farm Organization .225 .297 .655 .655 Member of a Social or Fraternal Crganization .032 .016 .637 Member of Michigan Horticultural Society, Community organization or Cooperative .AJO .392 .587 .586 FARM MANAGEMENT Farm Management Style .591 .598 .556 .556 Number of pieces of new machinery purchased in last two years .353 .350 .382 .39A Number of new chemicals used in last two years .BJA ._1; .A78 .A73 Number of new plants and seems used in last two years .Auy .AlA .603 .605 I - ‘.,.,.,- 4 ,,v..:e, , -, .lumber‘(3f new Iriiuecfit -e.in1.ques imped 1:; last two years .A57 .A59 .A96 -509 Contact with M.S.U. Experiment Station .3Al .535 .A9“ .600 Contact with M.S.U. Extension Service .123 .1A5 .282 .278 Feelings toward Group Bargaining .20] .202 .323 .307 Feelings toward worker unitnisation —.OA1 --— .081 --— LABOR MANAGEMENT Location of farmer during harvest .25A .251 .A62 .A63 Who corrects picking errors .855 .A79 .688 .707 % Migrants returning each year .297 .31A .271 .316 How do you get an adequate supply f labor .179 .173 .298 .289 A22 .u53 A78 .526 203 --- C1 F4 R.) \O O‘\ Who supervises picking, (chain of command) .2. 1—‘ \1'. O 1:— U.) 0 Does farmer share decision—making H \H) —\1 I l I o Fringe benefits (insurance) . When do you determine labor needs for upcoming season .263 .258 .3Al .32A What techniques does farmer use to keep workers coming back .113 .110 .328 .328 Employee relations .522 .508 .A97 .A78 FARM AS A FIRM Farm as a Firm .606 .60A --- —-— 81 In the following chapter we will utilize the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score as the dependent variable in a test of a series of structural variables. Following this, we will extract those items from the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score that seem to be the most powerful indica- tors and construct a second score which may be more par- simonious and perhaps a stronger score than that exhibited in the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. CHAPTER IV STRUCTURAL FACTORS AND ENTREPRENEURIAL FARM FIRMS In this chapter the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score will be treated as the dependent variable in a series of hypotheses utilizing various structural factors, or var- iables, as the independent variable. Structural factors may be defined as those factors imposed upon the farmer and his firm by the social structure within which it oper- ates, or as characteristics over which the individual farmer has little or no control, such as age or educational level. While some would not consider age or educational level as structural variables, they are considered as such in this study because they place the individual at a definite place within the social structure; thus they become structural within this context. It may be pointed out that some of these factors may be changed over time, such as level of capitalization or number of locations farmed, but they are considered to be relatively stable for the purposes of this study. The structural factors to be considered as the inde— pendent variables in this and the next chapter are: Size of Farm, Farmer's Relation to the Land, Number of Locations 82 83 Farmed, Education, Having a Full—Time Hired Man, Capitali- zation Level, Age, Number of Years the Farmer has Farmed, and whether or not he is a Full-Time Farmer. These varia- bles have found wide usage in the study of adoption of innovation,1 in looking at the phenomena of full—time versus part-time farmer,2 in the investigation of the small busi— 3 ness entrepreneur, and in the study of employer-employee relations in industry.“ Since the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score is a reflec- tion of the influence of the farmer entrepreneur on the farm firm, it may be expected that it will be highly correlated with the management ability of the farmer entrepreneur. lAlfred Dean, Herbert A. Aurbach, and C. Paul Marsh, "Some Factors Related to Rationality in Decision Making among Farm Operators," Rural Sociology, Vol. 23 (June, 1958), pp. 121-35. Rex R. Campbell, "A Suggested Paradigm of the Indi- vidual Adoption Process," Rural Sociology, Vol. 31 (Decem- ber, 1966), pp. “58-66. 2George A. Donohue, "Full-Time and Part-Time Farmers' Value Orientations Toward Social Institutions," Rural Sociology, Vol. 22 (September, 1957), pp. 221-29. Glenn V. Fugitt, "A Typology of the Part-Time Farmer," Rural Sociology, Vol. 26 (March, 1961), pp. 39-48. 3Norman R. Smith, The Entrepreneur and His Firm: The Relationship Between Type of Man and Type of Company, (EaSt Lansing: Bureau of Business and Economic Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Michigan State University, 1967). Orvis F. Collins and David G. Moore, with Darab B. Unwalla, The Enterprising Man (East Lansing: Bureau of Business and Economic Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Michigan State University, 1964). “Rensis Likert, New Patterns of Management (New York: McGraw—Hill Book Company, 1961). 84 Our purpose here is to determine the relationship of this score with the various factors that impinge upon the farmer entrepreneur in the performance of his entrepreneurial role. For the purposes of this study, correlational analy- sis will be used. With an N of 77, significance at the .05 per cent level is .227 while at the .01 per cent level it is .296. Size of Farm The size of the farms considered in this study ranged from 16 to 1500 acres. Following from our con- structed typology it might be expected that the larger the farming operation, the more adaptive the individual farmer entrepreneur would be. The hypothesis stated in the null form would be: "There is no relation between the size of the farm and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." However, when the size of farm was correlated with the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score an r of .545 was found. Since this r of .5A5 far exceeds the requirements for significance at the .01 per cent level the null hypothesis is rejected. There is a rela- tionship between the size of farm and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Since our typology indicates that the higher the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score the more adap- tive the farmer entrepreneur, we can state that the larger farm operators are generally more adaptive than are the smaller farm operators. 85 Farmer's Relation to the Land As pointed out in Chapter II, the Adaptive Farm Firm is dynamic in character and is increasing in size. Since the amount of available land is limited, the rap- idly expanding dynamic firm of the Adaptive Farmer Entre- preneur will probably be made up of land that is owned by the firm as well as additional land that is rented or leased. By way of contrast, the Rigid Farmer Entrepre- neur operates a static firm that is not expanding. Con- sequently, he would probably own all of the land that he operates, rather than taking on the additional responsi— bility of operating rented or leased land. The hypothesis stated in the null form would be: "There is no relationship between owning as well as renting or leasing land and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." The correlation coefficient of the variable "Owns all" or"Owns as well as rents or leases" and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score is .39“ which exceeds the requirements for significance at the .01 per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. There is a definite relationship between the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score and whether the farmer entrepreneur owns and rents or leases as opposed to owning all of the land that he oper- ates. Therefore, it may be said that those farmers who own as well as rent or lease will have higher Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Scores which indicates that they are 86 more adaptive than those farmers who own all of the land they operate. Numbers of Locations Farmed It might be expected that this variable would be highly related to the previous variable, "The Farmer's Relation to the Land." As pointed out in the construction of the typology, the rapidly expanding dynamic firm of the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer would be forced to seek additional land area to keep it in a competitive position. It is highly unlikely that this additional land would be available in a contiguous location to the major base of operations. Therefore, the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer would probably be farming in more than one location. The hypothesis in the null form would bezi "There is no relation between the number of locations farmed and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." The r produced by the correlation of the number of locations farmed with the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score was .Hl6, exceeding the requirements for significance at the l per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. There is a relationship between the number of locations farmed and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Thus, the data from this study tend to support the theoretical construction presented in the typology: the Adaptive Entrepreneurial Farmer will operate his farming enter- prise in more than one location. 87 As pointed out above, there would be a high relation- ship expected between whether the farmer owns all of his land or whether he owns as well as rents or leases his land and the number of locations that he farms. This is the general direction indicated by the high coefficients of correlation for the two variables "Farmer's Relation to the Land" with an r of .39“ and "Number of Locations Farmed" with an r of .U15. Education The median educational attainment for the farmer entrepreneurs in this study was 12 years while the median educational attainment for all rural farm males aged 1“ and over in Michigan in the year 1960 was 9 years.5 Therefore, we can see that this sample is somewhat atypi- cal and may exhibit some characteristics different from those of the male rural farm population of Michigan in general. The hypothesis in the null form would be: "There is no relationship between the educational attainment of the farmer entrepreneur and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." This analysis produced an r of .383, thereby exceeding the requirements for significance at the 1 per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. 5U.S. Bureau of the Census, U.S. Census of Pop- glation: 1960. General Social and Economic Character- istics Michigan. Final Report PC(1) - 2“ C, U.S. Govern— ment Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1962. 88 The evidence from this analysis indicates that there is a relationship between the educational attainment of the farmer entrepreneur and his adaptiveness as indicated by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Thus, we might say that those farmer entrepreneurs who are more highly educated would be more adaptive as indicated by their higher Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores. Does the Farmer Have a Full-Time Hired Man Since this study is concerned with the factors that are associated with management of the enterprise as well as labor management, it would seem that the size of the business enterprise needing full-time hired help would require that the farmer entrepreneur be up on his toes to keep the business at a viable level. We also would expect that there might be a relationship between size of farm and whether or not full—time help is required. Since there was a significant relationship expressed between the Size of Farm and the adaptiveness as expressed by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score, we might expect that there would be a relationship between the need for a full-time hired man and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Thehypothesis in the null form would be: "There is no relationship between having a full—time hired man and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." The test pro- duced an r of .362 which exceeds the requirements for 89 significance at the l per cent level. The null hypo- thesis is rejected. This analysis would demonstrate that there is a relationship between having a full—time hired man and the adaptiveness of the farmer entrepreneur as expressed by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. In general, this would support the theoretical construction of the typo- [p { logy in that the larger, more complex enterprises that t require additional full-time labor also would require that the farmer entrepreneur be more adaptive in his approach to farm and labor management. Capitalization Level As indicated earlier in this chapter, there is a relationship between size of farm and the adaptiveness of the farmer entrepreneur as expressed by the Entre- preneurial Farm Firm Score. We also would expect that there would be a relationship between the size of farm and the capitalization level, although the capitali- zation level was computed using information relating to investment in land, equipment, and improvements to the land (plantings of tree fruits), and may thus be con- sidered to be an approximation of net worth of the farmer entrepreneur. Data were not directly available regarding net worth of the farmer entrepreneur, so this alternative method was chosen. However, since the bulk of the 90 investment on the horticultural specialty crop farms is generally found in land and improvements to the land (tree fruit and small fruit plantings) we might expect that the more Rigid Farmer Entrepreneurs who own all of their land might have a higher net worth than do the more Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneurs who own as well as rent or lease additional land. Even though this relationship was expected, the data from this study did not necessarily support this. To subject this relationship to a test the hypothesis in the null form would be: "There is no rela— tionship between the Capitalization Level and the Entre- preneurial Farm Firm Score." The test produced an r of .671 which is by far the highest produced in this series of tests and greatly exceeds the requirements for signi- ficance at the l per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. There is a strong relationship between the level of capitalization and the adaptiveness of the farmer entre- preneur as measured by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Consequently, we might also conclude that even though the Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur may not own as much land as his more rigid counterpart, the total size and scope of his operation is large enough to require investments in additional inputs which would raise his level of capitalization above the Rigid Farmer Entrepre- neur who owns all of his land. 91 Ass Following from the construction of the Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm typology one might expect that there would be a relationship between the age of the farmer entrepreneur and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. One would expect from the typology that the younger farmer entrepreneurs who had started in business since the end ab“ of World War II would be more adaptive than those who i might be older. This could be justified by the fact that z the older farmer entrepreneurs may have solidified their r ways of thinking and operating prior to the rash of new technology that has been presented to the farmer during the past 20 years. Consequently, the null hypothesis would be: "There is no relationship between the age of the entrepreneurial farmer and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." This test produced an r of .212 which is below the level required for significance at the 5 per cent level. There is not sufficient evidence to reject the null hypo- thesis and state that there is a relationship between the age of the farm operator and his adaptiveness as expressed by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Therefore, there may be other factors which are more important than age when considering the adaptiveness of the entrepreneurial farmer. 92 Number of Years Farmed A high relationship between the variables of Age and Number of Years Farmed might be expected. In fact, when these two structural variables were correlated they pro- duced an r of .577 which by far exceeds requirements for significance at the l per cent level. With this being true, we also might expect that there would not be a sig- nificant relationship between the variable Number of Years Farmed and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. However, to test this relationship the null hypothesis would be: "There is no relationship between the Number of Years Farmed and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." The test produced an r of .083 which is below the require- ments for significance at the 5 per cent level. There is not sufficient evidence to reject the null hypothesis. Therefore, we do not have sufficient grounds on which to state that there is a relationship between the number of years a farmer entrepreneur has been in busi- ness and his adaptiveness as expressed by the Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Score. Full-Time Farmer From the constructed typology we might expect that the farmer entrepreneur would need to give his full attention to his own business enterprise, especially if he were concerned about its aggrandizement. We might expect that there would be a relationship between whether the farmer entrepreneur spends full time at his farm 93 business or whether he spends part of the year working elsewhere and his adaptiveness as measured by the Entre— preneurial Farm Firm Score. To test this relationship, the hypothesis in the null form is: "There is no relationship between being a full—time farmer and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score." This test produced an r of .022 which does not meet the requirements for significance at the 5 per cent level. There is not sufficient evidence to reject the null hypo- thesis. Therefore, we do not have sufficient grounds to expect that being a full-time farmer has any bearing on the adaptiveness of the farmer entrepreneur as expressed by the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. As pointed out in several places throughout this chapter, there would be expected high correlations between several of the structural variables considered in this chapter. Those variables which show a high cor— relation that might also follow from the constructed typology are: Size of Farm and Capitalization Level .712 Farmer's Relation to the Land and Number of Locations Farmed .485 Number of Acres Farmed and Farmer's Relation to the Land .519 Size of Farm and Full-Time Hired Man .479 Capitalization Level and Full-Time Hired Man .557 Age of Farm Operator and Number of Years Farmed .577 Age of Farm Operator and Educational Attainment —.239 All of these relationships are significant at the l per cent level with the exception of the relationship between 94 age and educational level. This relationship is signifi- cant at the 5 per cent level and since it is in the nega- tive direction it indicates that the younger farmer entre- preneurs have a higher educational attainment than do the older farmer entrepreneurs. In summary, we found that six of the nine variables considered in this chapter were significantly related to the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. These variables are: Size of Farm, Farmer's Relation to the Land, Number of Locations Farmed, Educational Level of the Farm Operator, Full-Time Hired Man, and Capitalization Level. Those three variables for which there was not sufficient evi- dence to give a significant relationship were: Age of the Farm Operator, Number of Years of Farming, and Full- Time Farmer. CHAPTER V CHANGE—TIME AS A KEY FACTOR The previous chapter treated numerous structural variables in relation to the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. It has been pointed out by Grove that Change— Time variables have better predictability over a long period of time than do the structural variables we have considered to date.1 Consequently, those variables in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score that have a Change or a Time dimension were extracted in an attempt to develop a more parsimonious score than the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Change and Time may best be defined in this con— text as those variables that give an indication of wil- lingness or lack of willingness to change, or that give an indication of present or future time orientation. As suggested by Grove thosevariables that give an indi- cation of willingness to change or that indicate a future time orientation have a higher predictability than do _ 1Ernest W. Grove, "Structural Analysis of Agricul- ture," Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 5 (Dec- ember, 1967), p. 1249. 95 96 the static structural variables about some future course of events.2 The variables selected to constitute the Change- Time Orientation Score for this study are: l. \OCIDNCEKTI 10. ll. 12. Number of Pieces of New Machinery Purchased in Last Two Years Number of New Chemicals Used in Last Two Years Number of New Plants and Seeds Used in Last Two Years Number of New Harvest Techniques Used in Last Two Years Contact with M.S.U. Experiment Station Contact with M.S.U. Extension Service Feelings toward Group Bargaining How Do You Get an Adequate Supply of Labor Who Supervises Picking (Chain of Command) Does Farmer Share Decision-Making When Do You Determine Labor Needs for the Up- coming Season Employee Relations 320 determine whether the Change-Time Orientation Score is a. more parsimonious indicator than the Entrepreneurial Fairm Firm Score, the Change-Time Orientation Score also w1.ll be treated as the dependent variable in a series of hyjpotheses utilizing the independent structural variables tessted in the previous chapter. It must be pointed out that these 12 variables that haves a Change-Time orientation have been extracted from h 2Grove, p. 1249. 97 the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. As indi- cated above, it is our purpose to determine whether this Change-Time score will be a more parsimonious indicator than the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score and still give us as good an indication of the relationship between the various structural variables to be considered as the larger, more complex 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm ‘“‘*“F‘Rp- i" Firm Score. Following the same procedure for scoring as was ht used for the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score, the range ' of possible scores for the Change-Time score would be 12 with the most Rigid Farmer Entrepreneurs having scores near the 0 end of the continuum and the most Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneurs having scores near the 12 end of the continuum. The actual distribution of the Change—Time scores will be found in Table 5. The Change-Time scores for each of the 77 farms included in the study will be found in Table 6. It will be noted from the inspection of Figure 3, a graphic presentation of the distribution of Change-Time scores, that the scores do not follow a normal distribution. However, as pointed out for the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores, with the small N irrvolved in the Study and the fact that the variables iflcluded in the score were operationalized from a con— Stnructed type, one cannot expect perfect normality in thee distribution of the scores. However, it will be 98 further noted that the Change—Time scores are not as erratic in their distribution as are the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Scores. TABLE 5.--Distribution of 12 variable Change-Time score. I“: ‘ ' Score Number of Respondents l 5 10 7 13 12 12 10 u 3 N = 77 OOGDNQU'IEWNH |._J To determine the contribution of each of the 12 variables in the Change-Time score to the total score, each variable was correlated with the total score. The variables and their correlation coefficients are pre- sented in Table 7. With an N of 77, each of the variables exceeds the requirements for significance at the .01 per cent level except the variable Contact with the M.S.U. Extension Service. This variable produced an r of .244 vflien correlated with the total Change-Time score which exceeds the requirements for significance at the .05 per cent level. Consequently, all 12 of those variables were retained and are included in the Change-Time score. In the remainder of this chapter the Change-Time score will 99 TABLE 6.--Individual farm firms and their Change—Time score. Change-Time Change-Time Farm # Score Farm # Score 1 7 41 9 2 9 42 9 3 8 43 8 4 6 44 2 5 3 45 2 6 3 46 3 7 7 47 2 8 10 48 3 9 8 49 4 10 1 5o 6 11 7 51 5 12 7 52 2 l3 6 53 7 14 3 54 6 15 7 55 3 16 4 56 5 l7 9 57 7 18 7 58 5 l9 6 59 6 20 5 60 6 21 5 61 6 22 8 62 10 23 10 63 2 24 8 64 6 25 6 65 7 26 5 66 6 27 3 67 8 28 7 68 5 29 8 69 5 30 7 7o 4 31 3 71 4 32 3 72 3 33 8 73 8 34 5 74 5 35 7 75 6 .36 4 76 5 137 8 77 5 338 4 359 4 5 100 14 13 I 12 L1 11 ‘0 . 'r—W' “III-m Number 8 of Respondents 7 .u——. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Change-Time Score Figure 3.—-Graphic representation of the distrib- ution of the 12 variable Change-Time score. 101 TABLE 7.--Corre1ation coefficients for the variables included in the Change-Time score. Coefficient of Variable Correlation with Change—Time Score Number of pieces of new machinery purchased in last two years .312 Number of new chemicals used in last two years .402 Number of new plants and seeds used in last two years .473 Number of new harvest techniques used in last two years .478 Contact with M.S.U. Experiment Station .485 Contact with M.S.U. Extension Service .244 Feelings toward group bargaining .301 How do you get an adequate supply of labor .297 Who supervises picking (chain of command) .339 Does farmer share decision making .415 When do you determine labor needs for the upcoming season .35“ Employee Relations .441 102 be treated as the dependent variable in a series of tests utilizing the structural variables considered as inde- pendent variables in Chapter IV. Size of Farm When the relationship of the Change-Time score to that of the Size of Farm is considered, we find the results are very similar to those found when the Entre— preneurial Farm Firm Score was related to the Size of Farm. For the purposes of this test, the hypothesis in the null form is: "There is no relationship between the size of farm and the Change—Time score." The test of this hypothesis produces an r of .466 which exceeds the requirements for significance at the 1 per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. In the analysis of this test we find that the Change-Time score corre- lated with the Size of Farm nearly as highly as did the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Farmer's Relation to the Land As indicated in the previous chapter, it would be expected that the more Adaptive Farmer Entrepreneur would probably own as well as rent or lease additional land for his operation. Therefore, to test the Farmer's Rela— tion to the Land with the Change—Time score the null hypothesis would be: "There is no relationship between owning as well as renting or leasing land and the Change- Time score." 103 The correlation coefficient of the Change-Time score with the variables "owns all" or "owns as well as rents or leases" is .377. This r exceeds the requirements for significance at the 1 per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. There is a relationship between owning all or owning as well as renting or leasing and the Change- Time score. Number of Locations Farmed When testing the null hypothesis: "There is no relation between the number of locations farmed and the Change-Time score," we find that the test produces an r of .374. This coefficient of correlation exceeds the requirements for significance at the l per cent level and the null hypothesis is rejected. There is a relationship between the number of locations farmed and the Change- Time score. This conclusion tends to support the constructed typology presented in Chapter II of this study. The constructed typology indicated that the Adaptive Entre- preneurial Farmer probably operates at more than one location. The results of this test do support the con- tention that farmers with a high Change-Time score operate at more than one location. jEducation When education is tested for a relationship with the Change-Time score, the hypothesis in the null form l" '-—-—- III—"v 1..» fix 3 $5. 104 would be: "There is no relationship between the educa- tional attainment of the farmer entrepreneur and the Change—Time score." This test produced an r of .295 which does not quite meet the requirements for signifi- cance at the l per cent level but does surpass the requirements for significance at the 5 per cent level. We can say that there is a relationship between the educational attainment of the farmer entrepreneur and the Change-Time score. This finding supports that re— ported earlier for the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Both of these scores are related to the educational attainment of the farmer entrepreneur and thus both tend to support the theoretical formulation in the con- structed typology. Does the Farmer Have a Full-Time Hired Man To test the relationship of this variable with the Change-Time score the null hypothesis is: "There is no relationship between having a full-time hired man and the Change-Time score." The test produces an r of .341 which exceeds the requirements for significance at the l per cent level. The null hypothesis is rejected. The results of this test are parallel to those reported in the last chapter for the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. There is a relationship between having a full—time hired man and the adaptiveness of the farmer entrepreneur as indicated by the Change-Time score. “3"“? ' I‘IT'T'TA: “9;? IL. 3H 6L. an ‘L 105 Capitalization Level As indicated in the previous chapter, one would expect a high degree of relationship between the Size of Farm and the Level of Capitalization. In fact, when these two structural variables were correlated we found ,an r of .719, which is extremely high. When we are testing the relationship between the Capitalization Level and the Change-Time score the null hypothesis would be: "There is no relationship between the Capitalization Level of the farmer entrepreneur and the Change-Time score." This test produced an r of .648 which far exceeds the requirements for significance at the 1 per cent level. This would mean that there is a high degree of relationship between the Capitalization Level of the farmer entrepreneur and the Change-Time score. This also would tend to support the theoretical formulation developed in the constructed typo- logy earlier in this study. Age As pointed out in the previous chapter, it was expected that there would be a demonstrated relationship between Age and the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. That test did not show a significant relationship. To. check this relationship using the Change-Time score, the funaothesis in the null form would be: "There is no rela- tionship between age and the Change-Time score." The test produced an r of .106 which does not meet the 106 requirements for significance at the 5 per cent level. There is not enough evidence to reject the null hypothesis. The results of this test then do support those reported for the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. There does not seem to be a relationship between the age of the farmer entrepreneur and his adaptiveness as illus— trated through the Change-Time score. Number of Years Farmed As was pointed out in the last chapter, it was expected that the number of years farmed would be related to the age of the farmer entrepreneur, and when these two structural variables were correlated the test pro- duced an r of .577 which exceeds requirements for sig- nificance at the 1 per cent level. Tests involving the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score did not produce results that were statistically significant. To determine whether results involving the Change-Time score are similar, the null hypothesis is: "There is no relationship between the number of years farmed and the Change-Time score." This test produced an r of .051 which is far below the requirements for significance at the 5 per cent level. There is not sufficient evidence to reject the null hypo— thesis. It does not seem as if there is any relationship between the number of years farmed and the Change—Time score. This test would corroborate the results found in the previous chapter. 107 Full-Time Farmer When the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score was tested against whether or not the farmer entrepreneur devoted his full time to the farming operation, there did not appear to be any relationship. To test this variable against the Change—Time score the null hypothesis would be: "There is no relationship between being a full-time 1““ farmer and the Change-Time score." The test produced an i r of .058 which is far below the requirements for signi- j ficance at the 5 per cent level. There is not sufficient I evidence to reject the null hypothesis. This test also tends to support the results found in the last chapter for this variable and the Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Score. There does not seem to be a relationship between being a full-time farmer and the adaptiveness of the farmer entrepreneur as indicated by the Change-Time score. Discussion It was found in all cases that the Change-Time score gave similar results when tested against the above struc- tural variables as did the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Significant relationships were found with the same six variables: Size of Farm, Farmer's Relation to the Land, Number of Locations Farmed, Educational Attain— ment of the Farmer Entrepreneur, Full—Time Hired Man, and Capitalization Level. The three variables for which no 108 significant relationship was found are: Age of Farmer Entrepreneur, Number of Years Farming, and Full-Time Farmer. In all cases the Change-Time score gave slightly lower coefficients of correlation, but only in one case, that of Education, did it move the relationship below the l per cent level of significance to that of being significant at only the 5 per cent level. Therefore, it may be concluded that the Change- Time score is sufficiently powerful to give results simi- lar to the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. Since the Change—Time score includes only 12 variables as opposed to the 21 found in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score, the Change-Time score may be considered to be more par- simonious and still give the desired results. For a com— parison of the coefficients of correlation for the Entre- preneurial Farm Firm Score and the Change-Time score and the nine structural variables considered above, see Table 8. 109 TABLE 8.--Corre1ation coefficients for the structural variables and the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm score and the 12 variable Change- Time score. I 4 Entrepreneurial Change- Structural Variable Farm Firm score Time Score Acres farmed .54494 .46633 Relation to the land .39379 .37740 Number of locations farmed .41504 .3737? Age .21234 .10562 Education .38297 .29520 Number of years farmed .08298 .05130 Full—time farmer .02192 .05821 Hired man (full-time) .36193 .34127 Capitalization level .67076 .64754 CHAPTER VI SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS As was pointed out earlier, the purpose of this study is to: "study the relationship between the farmer and his firm and the pattern of labor management prac— tices that he utilizes." To do this, the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology was developed in which the polar types were characterized as being "Rigid" and "Adaptive." In constructing these types, data were drawn from the litera- ture dealing with farm management and from the interview protocols of the larger study. The constructed typology contained four sub-types: Social Participation, Farm Management, Labor Management, and The Farm as a Firm. The constructed Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology was operationalized through a series of 21 variables listed in Chapter III. The farmer entrepreneurs in the sample were scored as being either Rigid or Adaptive on each of these 21 variables. The composite of this scoring formed the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score. To determine whether a more parsimonious indicator Could be developed, 12 variables that had either a change or a time dimension were extracted from the 21 variable Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score and formed into a Change- 110 111 Time score. These two scores, the Entrepreneurial Farm Ffih Score and the Change-Time score, formed the opera— tionalization of the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology. To test their applicability, they were each correlated with a series of structural variables. In each case the results of the correlation analysis were similar. In all, a significant relationship was found between the scores and six of the structural variables. They are: Farmer's Relation to the Land, Number of Locations Farmed, Educational Attainment, whether or not the farmer employed a Full-Time Hired Man, and the Level of Capitalization of the farm enterprise. There was no significant relationship found between three of the struc— tural variables and the scores. These variables are: Age, Number of Years Farmed, and whether or not the Farmer Devotes All of His Time to the Farming Operation. Since the results of the correlational analysis for the two scores and these nine structural variables were very similar, it may be concluded that the Change- Time score is as effective an operationalization of the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm continuum as is the Entrepre- neurial Farm Firm Score. Since the Change-Time score contained only 12 variables as opposed to the 21 variables contained in the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score it is also a more parsimonious indicator. .g- h 5“. WLII‘ flu” 112 While it was expected that there would be a high correlation between Age and the Number of Years Farmed and the two scores, the absence of this might be explained by a third factor. Since there was a significant rela- tionship between the level of education of the farmer entrepreneur and his adaptiveness as indicated by the two scores we might expect to find that there was a relation- ship between these two variables and educational attain- ment. In fact, correlational analysis showed that Age and Number of Years Farmed were identically related to Education, both giving an r of -.238. While this rela— tionship is significant at only the 5 per cent level and it is negative, it indicates that the younger farmers who had been in business fewer years had a significant relationship to educational attainment. Consequently, even though our original analysis indicated that there was no significant relationship between Age or the Number of Years Farmed and the two scores measuring Adaptiveness, if we had controlled for Education there probably would have been a significant relationship. In attempting to determine why there was no sig- nificant relationship between whether or not the farmer devotes all of his time to the farming operation and the two scores measuring Adaptiveness we might only say that at this point in time, the data of this study do not support the theoretical formulation presented in the 113 constructed type. We might hypothesize that the time has not yet come when it will be possible for a farmer entre- preneur to devote his attention to other pursuits than farming and still maintain a viable farm enterprise. We also might point out that in the way in which this sample was selected, a number of entrepreneurs who own other businesses or work full time at a trade fell into the sample. While they perform the entrepreneurial role as far as the farming operation is concerned they also are employed full time in some other enterprise. Analysis of the case studies would indicate that a number of these individuals could be classified as Adaptive Farmer Entre- preneurs and perhaps it is because of their involvement in other pursuits, rather than in spite of these pur- suits, that they are more adaptive. By the mere fact that they are not able to give their full attention to the farming Operation they have so structured the enter- prise that it is possible to operate it fairly effec- tively without their full-time attention. It will remain for further investigation with dif- ferent population of farmer entrepreneurs to determine whether in fact the three variables of Age, Number of Years Farmed, and whether or not the Farmer Devotes All Of His Time to the Farming Operation are highly related tO adaptiveness as indicated in the constructed type when they are measured by one of the scores. 114 In general, the utility of constructing a typology to assist in the explanation of the empirical world is demonstrated by this study. The Entrepreneurial Farm Firm typology identifies the variables that are important in explaining the unique characteristics of the various types of farm operators. The utility of this continuum will come as it provides the basis for further investi- a gation of the farm management-labor management phenomena by other investigators. Although it would be desirable to cast the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score, or the more i parsimonious Change-Time score, in the role of a predic- tive or independent variable, it was not possible to do so at this time. The way in which the score was developed would have led to extreme circularity if the score(s) had been placed in the predictive role. However, there is evidence to indicate that those farmers who score high on these scores will also score high on Farm management and Labor Management ability. It will remain for further investigation to determine directly the predictive abi- lity of these scores relative to Farm Management and Farm Labor Management in general. There are numerous limitations to this study which include the size and selectivity of the sample of farmer enterpreneurs. While we may state that the sample is representative of all fruit and vegetable growers in Mich- iSan who employ migrant seasonal labor, we cannot gen- eralize directly to all farm operators. It will remain 115 for further investigation to determine whether the typo- logy developed in this study will be applicable to a broader spectrum of commercial agriculture. Since the larger study was exploratory in nature, the limits of the data from that study are reflected in this analysis. The larger study relied upon tape-recorded interviews as a major means of collecting data. While ? h \‘14- 3*— 4 these interview protocols provided rich materials for the case studies presented in this dissertation, the Wu-«--—:-— 3 coding of concrete data from these interview protocols was, in many cases, subjective at best. Even with the shortcomings of the exploratory nature of the larger study, the lessons learned here will be invaluable in framing future research on this subject. It will be pos- sible to develop a more tightly knit interview schedule which will produce data that will lend themselves more readily to quantification than did the data in this study. Even with the limitations expressed here, there are findings from this study which will have direct applica- bility to social science practitioners, especially those who are concerned with improving the Farm Management and Farm Labor Management skills of farmer entrepreneurs. While we were not able to cast the Entrepreneurial Farm Firm Score or the more parsimonious Change-Time score in the role of an independent variable the evidence does 116 indicate that there is a high relationship between these scores and Farm Management and Farm Labor Management ability. It should be possible for these social science practitioners to develop a series of questions to pose to the farmer entrepreneur based on the variables included in these scores which will let the farmer entrepreneur measure his Farm Management or Farm Labor Management abi- lity. Were he to score towards the rigid end of the con- tinuum on any of the variables included in the score then he could further examine the causes of this low score and with the assistance of social science practitioners and others develop an ameliorative program which would help him to move towards the more adaptive end of the con- tinuum, and consequently, become more effective at Farm Management and Farm Labor Management. BIBLIOGRAPHY Bishop, C. E., ed. Farm Labor in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press, 1967. Butz, Dale E. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agri- culture: The Effects of Off Farm Employment Inputs." 4- Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). 7 Campbell, Rex R. "A Suggested Paradigm of the Individual , Adoption Process." Rural Sociology, Vol. 31 (1966). r Cole, Arthur H. "Entrepreneurship and Entrepreneurial History: The Institutional Setting." Change and the Entrepreneur. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1949. Collins, Orvis F.; Moore, David G.; with Unwalla, Darab B. The Enterprising Man. East Lansing: Bureau of Busi- ness and Economic Research, Graduate School of Busi— ness Administration, Michigan State University, 1964. Danhof, Clarence H. "Observations on Entrepreneurship in Agriculture." Change and the Entrepreneur. Cam- bridge: Harvard University Press, 1959. Dean, Alfred; Aurbach, Herbert A.; and Marsh, C. Paul. "Some Factors Related to Rationality in Decision Making among Farm Operators." Rural Sociology, Vol. 23 (1958). Donohue, George A. "Full-Time and Part—Time Farmers' Value Orientations Toward Social Institutions." Rural Sociology, Vol. 22 (1957). Edwards, Everett E. "American Agriculture--The First 300 Years." Farmers in a Changing World, 1940 Yearbook of Agriculture. Washington, D.C.: Superintendent of Documents, 1940. Fuguitt, Glenn V. "A Typology of the Part-Time Farmer." Rural Sociology, Vol. 26 (1961). Fuller, Varden. "Emerging Farm Labor Issues." Washing- ton: Paper presented at 44th Annual National Agri- cuggural Outlook Conference, Tuesday, November 15, 19 . 117 118 Fuller, Varden and Beale, Calvin L. "Impact of Socio- economic Factors on Farm Labor Supply." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 5 (December, 1967). Fuller, Varden. Labor Relations in Agriculture. Berkeley: Institute for Industrial Relations, University of California, 1955. Glaser, Barney G. and Strauss, Anslem L. The Discovepy of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Quantitative Research. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company, 1967. Headley, J. C. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agri- culture: How Can It be Recognized." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Hecht, Reuben W. "Farm Labor Situation-Trends and Forces at Work." Lincoln: Paper presented at National Extension Workshop on Farm Labor Problems, Univer- sity of Nebraska Center for Continuing Education, November 1-4, 1966. Hoselitz, Bert F. "The Early History of Entrepreneurial Theory." Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, Vol. 3 (19511. Kelsey, Myron P. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: Is It an Art or a Science." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Kennedy, Rex P. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: New Tools for the Manager." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Lee, Shu-Ching. "The Theory of the Agricultural Ladder." Agricultural Histopy, Vol. 21. Likert, Rensis. New Patterns of Management. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1961. MacGillivray, John H. and Stevens, Robert A. Agricul- tural Labor and its Effective Use. Palo Alto: The National Press, 1964. McKinney, John C. Constructive Typology and Social Theory. New York: Meredith Publishing Company, 1966. Merton, Robert K. Social Theory and Social Structure. Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1957. —| uh... . I" all-in “NI, ‘Ir any '3 ".0 I... -'.' n .‘L 4”. 119 Nelson, Aaron G. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: How Can It Be Improved." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Padfield, Harland and Martin, William E. Farmers, Workers and Machines: Technological and Social Change in Farm Industries of Arizona. Tuscon: The University of Arizona Press, 1965. Quenemoen, M. F. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: The Influence of Values and Goals." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Redlich, Fritz. "The Origin of the Concepts of Entrepre- neur and Creative Entrepreneur." Explorations in Entrepreneurial Histopy, Vol. 1, No. 2 (19491. Rieck, Robert E. "The Management Factor in Commercial Agriculture: How Can It Be Taught." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 47 (December, 1965). Rogers, Everett M. Diffusion of Innovation. New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1962. Rural Manpower Center. "A Study of Interpersonal Rela- tions Among Managers and Employees of Fruit and Vegetable Farms with Emphasis on Labor Management Practices Utilized." East Lansing: Proposal sub- mitted to the Director, Office of Manpower Policy, Evaluation and Research, U.S. Department of Labor, May 12, 1966. Rushton, Willard T. and Shaudys, E. T. " A Systematic Conceptualization of Farm Management." Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 49 (February, 1967). Schumpeter, Joseph H. "Economic Theory and Entrepreneurial History." Change and the Entrepreneur. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1949. Shannon, Fred A. American Farmers' Movements. Princeton: D. Van Nostrand Company, Inc., 1957. Smith, Norman R. The Entrepreneur and His Firm: The Relationship Between Type of Man and Type of Com- pany. East Lansing: Bureau of Business and Eco- nomic Research, Graduate School of Business Admin- istration, Michigan State University, 1967. Strauss, J. H. "The Entrepreneur: The Firm." Journal of Political Economy, LII (1944). 120 Sturt, Daniel W. "Farm Labor in 1980." Research Report 48 - Farm Business, East Lansing: Agricultural Experiment Station and Cooperative Extension Ser- vice, Michigan State University, 1966. Taylor, Paul S. "Plantation Laborer Before the Civil War." Agricultural History, Vol. 28. U.S. Bureau of the Census. U.S. Census of Population: Wohl, 1960. General Social and Economic Characteristics Michigan. Final Report PC(1) — 24 C, U.S. Govern- ment Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1962. R. Richard. "The Rags to Riches Story: An Epi- sode of Secular Idealism." Class, Status, and Power: A Reader in Social Stratification. Edited by Reinhard Bendix and Seymour M. Lipset. Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1953. a -A—‘_lt u n APPENDICES 121 . .__' "1"..“7 pl APPENDIX I INTERVIEW SCHEDULE 122 {‘4‘ !a_-. F.4- I to-“ . ‘ LA-.- . . ‘| m .. 7""! ‘ FARMER INTERVIEW 1967 FARM LABOR STUDY Rural Manpower Center Department of Sociology Entree l. RMC and Sociology Study 2. Both Agriculture and Worker Interest 3. What are Labor—Management Problems? 4. Confidential - tape only for ease. Name Address Location 123 D r_‘ 124 1. How many acres do you farm? acres owned acres rented acres(other--managed, leased, etc. Specify) 2. At how many different locations do you farm? 2a. How far apart are these farms? 3. How many acres of the following fruits and vegetables did you have last year? Early Approx. Med. Processing Sell Acres Varieties? Late? or Fresh? Dates Apples No. Trees Peaches No. Trees Pears No. Trees Plums & Prunes No. Trees Cherries, tart No. Trees Cherries, sweet No. Trees Blueberries Raspberries Strawberries Grapes No. Vines of bearing age 125 Acres Varieties? Other Fruits (Specify) Early Med. Late? Processing or Fresh? Approx. Sell Dates Vegetables Cantaloupes and Muskmelons Tomatoes Pickles and Cucumbers Asparagus Dry Onions Carrots Cauliflower Lettuce and Romaine Potatoes Sweet Peppers Other Vegetables (Specify) _ 4. 126 Have you used any new pieces of machinery on your oper- ation in the last 2 years? Plowing or Discing? Pruning? Planting? Cultivating? Spraying? Fertilizing? Harvesting? Materials Handling? (Graders, augers, lifts) Trucks? Tractors? Other (Specify) What new chemicals have you used in the last two years? (Be specific with respect to name of chemical, name of variety and which particular crop this involved.) k What new varieties of plants or seeds have you used in the last two years? 10. 127 What new pruning, spraying or cultivation techniques have you started to use in the last two years? What new harvesting procedures have you employed in the last two years? .‘iI-‘HJL : 3 What new storage facilities or procedures have you em- ployed in the last two years? In the last year, have you had any personal contact with? Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes No Q-OO‘DJ UHU‘OQHJCD . M.S.U. Experiment Station? . Farmers' Week? Extension Service? County ASC Office? (Title, lime, allotments, etc.) Soil Conservation Service? County Welfare Department? . Michigan Migrant Opportunity (OEO)? Health Department? Department of Labor? Farm Labor Service (MESC)? 11. 12. 13. l4. 15. 128 Are you a member of: ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer Farm Bureau Federation ___Yes ____No ___ Officer Grange ___Yes ___ No ____Officer NFO ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer Farmers' Union ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer Michigan Horticulture Society? Commodity Association? ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer [_ ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer { __Yes _ No _ Officer 5 ___Yes ___ No ____Officer F Farm Coop. WY ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer Lodge ___Yes ___ No ____Officer Church Service Org. (Lions, Kiwanis) ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer ___Yes ___ No ___ Officer Social Group (card club, square dance, etc.) ___Yes ____No ___ Officer Yes No Officer As far as political party is concerned, do you consider yourself a: Republican Democrat Independent (Refused to answer) How old are you? How many years of school have you had? How long have you been farming? 129 16. I'd like to find out how much labor is involved in your operation here. I would like to estimate, roughly, how many full days you spend in farm work. 16a. First, do you have any work off the farm? (Winter job or custom farm labor) days per year? What months do you work? Where work? Work any Sundays? Saturdays? Vacations? Half-days in Winter? 3%.” (307 work days excluding Sundays and holidays) (255 work days excluding above and Saturdays) Total Work Days on Farm Last Year 17. How many days of work per year does your wife contribute? 130 18. How many days (or months) are worked by the following people during these seasons? TYPE OF LABOR Family: Names, rela- tionship and ages of family labor Spring or Planting Growing (or Summer) Harvest Winter Total Full Time Hired Men (Names) Local Laborers Names (If just a few) or categories (e.g., H.S. Boys) 131 19. How many days would you say were spent by migrant on your farm last year? What month? __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __(No.) families of __(No. __crews of __ workers for __crews of __ workers for __crews of __ workers for __crews of __ workers for __crews of __ workers for Single workers for Other: workers workers workers workers workers workers workers workers ___weeks. weeks. weeks. weeks. weeks. weeks. workers for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. for __(No.) weeks. Crew leader's name Crew leader's name Crew leader's name Crew leader's name Crew leader's name 132 20. I'd like to get some idea of when the seasons begin. When does Spring work start? When does Spring work stop and growing season begin? When does Harvest start? When does it end? (Mark in the seasons for 3 major crops) (Crop) Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. ,Jlllllllllll Winter ‘ Spring Growing Harvest Winter (Crop) Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. JIVJJJJJJ llll Winter Spring Growing Harvest Winter (Crop) Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. I.l|1lJlllllJ Winter Spring Growing Harvest Winter . D - . i‘ L: ii I. __q. .- V‘m . ' 133 (TURN ON THE TAPE RECORDER) 21. Now we'd like to find out what things you and your workers do during these seasons. We want to know what major farm operations occur at certain times. A. Spring or Planting Season. What major operations occur then? (Plant beans, prepare ground, or prune trees) (Rely on Tape Recorder) Farm Operation Who works What does Where What is or Task with whom? each do? done? Work Flow? [2.5 B. What major operations are done during the summer or growing season? (e.g., Spraying, thinning, cultivating, etc.) Farm Operation Who works What does Where What is or Task with whom? each do? done? Work Flow? 134 C. What major operations are done around harvest time? (e.g, Pick Apples, Store Fruit, Delivery to Processor, etc.) (Rely on Tape Recorder) Farm Operation Who works What does Where What is or Task with whom? each do? done? Work Flow? D. What major operations are done in the Winter months? (e.g., Package, Repair equipment, Prune, etc.) (Rely on Tape Recorder) Farm Operation Who works What does Where What is or Task with whom? each do? done? Work Flow? 135 WORKER REWARDS 22. 23. How is their pay determined? (e.g., piece rate, hourly 24. 25. 26. 27. What do you pay your workers? a. Full time? $ per month b. Family? $ c. Local? $ per hour d. Migrant? $ per hour bonus) What other fringe benefits do you provide? Insurance Food Housing Utilities Car or Gas Other “3000603 What is the average number of (bushels, quarts, lugs, pounds) picked per man hour? 25a. How much variation is there among workers? Which employees on your farm have increased their wages and rates of pay since they have been employed by you? Which of your workers while being employed by you have made a step up as far as getting more desirable job and/or one with more responsibility? jmfi" -— 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. What 136 jobs do your workers want or try to get? (e.g., drive tractor or truck, crew leader, etc.) What jobs are undesirable so that workers avoid them? What is your policy on starting times? a. Quitting times? b. Length of rest periods? 0. Vacations? What do your workers do around here for recreation? When was most of your migrant housing built? a. Average size room for a family? (in feet) b. Cabins, motel, barn, house? c. How are the units furnished? d. Where is water supply? Where are bathrooms located? 137 LABOR PROCUREMENT Note: The remaining questions should be asked about full time workers and seasonal workers. Questioning should evolve around times when seasonal workers are on the job, only. This will usually be harvest- ing and may include cultivating. 33. Now let's take each kind of labor you have here on the farm and find out how you found the labor you now have. 34. How did you find your full time workers? a. MESC, magazine or newspaper, informal contact? b. What was the se uence of contacts? (who saw who first and where?) c. Where was this person located when he was re ? d. What was he doing at that time? e. Did you know him before? f. Was this person recommended? How? 35. How many full time hired men have you had in the past 3 years? 36. Why did each leave? (Note: Inquire about last 5 only) 1. found a better job (1) (2) (3) 2. was fired 3. other reasons, family, etc. U‘lt‘wNH . v I -.---*s-_-J V-n\gm‘--.F_.Mflag I... 138 Seasonal Labor. 37. 38. 39. 40. 41. Have you been able to employ local labor? Yes No (Note: If yes, return to Question 34) (If no, continue to question 38) When do you try to determine the amount of labor needed for the upcoming year? 1. During the Winter 2. During the Growing Season 3. Just before Harvest 8‘ When were you sure you had enough laborers last year? month How do you go about getting an adequate supply of migrant workers? What techniques do you have to keep your workers coming back? a. Contact during Winter? b. Write them? c. Send them money? _e d. Pay their transportation? 42. What per cent of your seasonal laborers return each year? (Take last 3 years) ' ‘ 43. Do you have a written labor contract? Yes No a. What is in it? TRAINING 44. What kind of experience did the worker(s) have before he (they) started here? 139 45. What kind of training did your workers require when he (they) came on the job? a. How did you go about training him? b. Specific periods of explanation or mostly on-the- job training? c. How long did it take to train this worker? d. What are the main problems in training this (these) employee(s)? ." :1 Jfi-"a—uq DECISION MAKING 46. What kinds of decisions do you make by yourself? (Give examples) 47. Who decides what the labor will do, usually? a. When are decisions made about what this worker will do? . Start of Season? . At start of each job or operation? First part of each week? Every day? Morning or evening? When he runs out of work? U'IJZ'LUTUH b. How important are they in deciding things around here, usually? (Note: Try to establish which category) . Many things they decide on their own. . Their opinions are accepted many times. Their opinions are listened to and taken into account, but others usually decide on their own. They really never have much of a voice in things. 4:- LUMP 140 CHAIN OF COMMAND 48. Who gives the orders and instructions around here? (Note: get examples) 49. To whom do you usually give orders? 50. What kinds of orders or instructions do you give to employees? Note: Get examples. a. How does this change during Harvest or peak work load times? 51. Do you have some special techniques of giving direc- tions to that works best for you? SUPERVISION 52. To what extent does get involved in checking and supervising the work here on your farm? a. Who does he supervise? b. When does he supervise? c. What operations does he supervise? d. How goodzajob of supervising does he do? 553. Who supervises the work of ? 514. How do you go about supervising ? a. Working with him till he knows how? (b) How does this change with each task? (focus on Harvest) 555. How do you check on the quality of work of ? a. How often do you check? b. How does this change by the season? c. How does this change depending on the operation? 56 . lfihat operations require close supervision? 57’- Vflhat operations require very little supervision? 141 58. Once you have checked on the work and find it unsatis- factory, what do you say or do to to improve the work? a. Set an example? b. Show him the operation again? 0. Tell him to change? d. Get crew leader or hired man to watch more closely? e. Get someone else to do the job? f. Let them know they either improve or get less pay, maybe even get fired? 59. In general, what are your major problems in supervising labor? (Probe) 60. What are some of your favorite techniques that work best in supervising workers? (Probe) RESPONSIBILITY 61. How dependable is in seeing that a job gets done? 62. Is he able to take on responsibility? 63. If you have to leave the farm during an important operation, can take responsibility and carry on with the job? 64. Have you ever tried to see just how much responsibility can assume? 65. Are there certain jobs where is responsible and others where he (they) is (are) not? a. What jobs are these? 142 CONFLICT 66. We know everybody has disagreements at some time or other with their workers. What were some of the major disagreements or misunderstandings in the last few years? (Probe for 3-4 situations) Housing? Pay? . Drinking? Stealing? Showing up on time? Work completion? 1 Crop damage? Busting equipment? | Working long enough? :3 m *a m Cl 0 :7 m Finances? 67. Have you fired any workers in the last few years? Why? 68. What type of work group (nationality, single work units vs. group, type of group--all male or couple) do you have the most problems with? a. Nationality? Singles vs. Groups? Single male, couples, or marrieds? Experienced vs. unexperienced? Other? (DO-IOU 69. In general, what are the biggest problems with labor? a. What are the most frequent problems? b. Conflict among workers? 70. After considering these problems, what's left in it for you? That is, do you make any money? a. What was your average Gross Income in the last 2 years? b. What was your average net income? Roughly speaking, how much do you have invested in your operation? d. Of the total you have invested, what percentage, roughly, of it is borrowed money? 71. 72. 143 Has anybody or any group talked recently about Group Bargaining for better prices? a. What do you think of this for the future? Are you aware of any unionization activities among farm workers? a. What is your opinion of this movement? b. What do you think people around here will do if unionization is started? APPENDIX II OBSERVATION GUIDE 144 gm.- . . elm-in. 3.- OBSERVATION GUIDE Name Address Outline map of farm operation(s) showing position of major buildings and migrant housing: 145 146 MIGRANT HOUSING Type of construction: Size of units: Condition: Location & Type of bathrooms: Is there hot water available? Yes Is there a shower house? Yes Are there laundry facilities Yes Describe shower and laundry facilities: No No No 147 DECISION MAKING When are decisions made about what workers will do? Start of the season? At the start of each job or operation? First part of each week? Every day? Morning, noon, night (circle appropriate time) When they run out of work? 42'me U1 Describe: 148 CHAIN OF COMMAND 1. Who usually gives orders? 1a. Is there a chain of command apparent? Yes No If yes - what is it? 2. To whom are the orders usually given? 149 SUPERVISION 1. To what extent does the farmer get involved in checking (quality, etc.) the work of the workers? spend his time? a. b. In the field with the workers In the packing shed Spraying, discing, etc. Transporting crop to market Other (spec.) Other (spec.) Describe: How does the farmer (manager) or principle supervisor 150 How is unsatisfactory work corrected: a. Set an example b. Show worker the operation again 0. Tell worker to change d. Get crew to talk to worker e. Tell crew leader to watch the worker f. Have hired man employee watch Have hired man Have hired man Chi-“5'09 or other full time the worker correct the worker speak to crew leader Get someone else to do the job Let them (worker) know they have to improve or else get docked or maybe 'fired Describe: