N CDC!) WWW“INIIHWlUllHHllfih“HIWWHMMI ITH I {TI-list: 300? This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Three Essays on Business Cycle and Monetary Policy presented by Yongjae Choi has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Economics Ph. D. gree in V Ma' r Professor’s Signature 1 June, 2006 Date MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution -w w __..__ __.k- 7 LIBRARY Michigan State University " V “" C PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 2/05 p:/ClRC/DaleDue.indd~p.1 THREE ESSAYS ON BUSINESS CYCLE AND MONETARY POLICY B \ Yongjae C hoi A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2006 ABSTRACT THREE ESSAYS ON BUSINESS CYCLE AND MONETARY POLICY BV v. Yongjae Choi It is well known that monetary policy can have different consequences across sectors. However, the recent discussion about optimal monetary policy has often ignored the sectoral impacts of monetary policy actions since aggregate inflation and output are thought to be main policy concerns. The first chapter demonstrates that if people care only about their own sector or industry. monetary policy makers should pay attention to the stabilization of sectoral inflations and output gaps rather than aggregated variables. T 0 address the issue. we construct a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with sticky prices and two sectors: durable and nondurable goods. Simulation results show that while following optimal policy rules to target aggregated variables results in poor outcomes under discretion, optimal policy rules designed to target disaggregated variables. such as strict output gap targeting and durable goods sector targeting, yield results close to the optimal preconnnitment equilibrium. The second chapter investigates the role of durability of goods to generate the substantial effect of money on output and inflation. Following the strand of New- Keynesian research, price stickiness is introduced into a two sector model so that a monetary Shock has a non- negligible real effect. We show that durability can change output and inflation dynamics in important ways. This effect happens through two channels: consumer’s intratemporal consumption decision over two goods: durable and nondurable, and firm’s backward-looking price setting decision due to durability of goods. Simulation results show that even though durability can account for the inertia in inflation and persistence in output together, it. can help to more convincingly explain inertia in inflation. The third chapter estimates N ew—Ix'eynesian structural model and evaluates alter- native monetary policy regimes. Estimated two sector model and alternative policy regimes are used to calculate the optimal monetary policy frontier. The structural model that consists of two sectors: durable and nondurable, is estimated by the Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML). Given the structure of the economy and discretionary monetary policy regimes, we find that changes in monetary policy re- sponses to aggregate or disaggregate inflation and output gap can imply substantial differences in long-run inflation and output variances. More importantly, this chapter shows that in terms of monetary policy frontier, monetary policy could have been more effective if the central bank had focused on sectoral stabilization as opposed to traditional stabilization. To My Parents iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank first. of all my advisor, Rowena Pecchenino for her suggestions and encouragements. I am slao in debt with my other committee members, Raoul Minetti, Luis Araujo, and Long Chen for helpful comments and suggestions. Throughout all the hours of Ph.D program, my parents encouraged me with love and belief. This dissertation is just the fruits of their love and commitment. I also would like to thank Kyongl‘iwa Jeong for her invaluable advice and friendship. Contents LIST OF TABLES LIST OF FIGURES 1 Optimal Monetary Policy in Two Sector Model 1.1 Introduction ................................ 1.2 The Model ................................. 1.2.1 Households ............................ 1.2.2 Firms ............................... 1.3 Optimal Monetary Policy .‘ .v i ...................... 1.3.1 Policy Objective Function .................... 1.3.2 Configuration of the model .................... 1.3.3 Calibration and Results ..................... 1.4 Optimal Policy Design .......................... 1.5 The Role of Durability and Relative Price Stickiness . 1.6 Conclusion ................................. 2 Two Sector Business Cycle: Durable and Nondurable Goods 2.1 Introduction ................................ 2.2 The Model ................................. 2.2.1 Households ............................ 2.2.2 Firms ............................... 2.3 IVIulti-Periods Case ............................ vi viii ix 10 13 15 16 17 29 32 35 37 37 39 2.3.1 Three Periods Case . . . ooooooooooooooooooooo 2.3.2 Aggregate Demand and Supply Equation ............ 2.3.3 N-Period Case ........................... 2.4 Simulation ................................. 2.4.1 Stylized Facts ........................... 2.4.2 Monetary Policy ......................... 2.4.3 Main Results ........................... 2.4.4 Sensitivity Analysis ........................ 2.5 Conclusion ................................. 3 Econometric Policy Evaluation in Two Sector Model 3.1 Introduction ................................ 3.2 The Structural Model ........................... 3.3 Data and Preliminary Estimation .................... 3.4 Discretionary Policy and Loss Function ................. 3.5 Estimation and Optimal Policy Frontier ................ 3.5.1 Parameter Estimates ....................... 3.5.2 Optimal Policy Frontier 3.5.3 Sensitivity Analysis . . . 3.6 Conclusion ............ A Appendix Bibliography vii 46 47 48 50 50 57 62 64 64 66 68 72 74 74 76 79 82 84 87 List of Tables 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 Baseline Parameters ........................... 19 Outcomes in the Case of a Cost Shock ................. 24 Outcomes in the Case of Aggregate Demand Shocks .......... 26 Outcomes in the Case of Alternative Objective Function ....... 28 Outcomes of Alternative Delegations Schemes and Optimal Taylor Rule 31 The Welfare Loss (104) of the Change of Durability (6) ........ 33 The Welfare Loss (104) of the Change of Relative Price Stickiness (an, ad) .................................. 34 Estimation Results of the Intertemporal IS Equation ......... 69 Estimation Results of the Phillips Curve ................ 71 Estimation Results of the Reaction Function .............. 72 Results of FIML Estimation ....................... 75 viii List of Figures 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 The Real GDP, the Inflation Rate and the Federal Funds Rate . . . . 3 The Impulse Responses of Sectoral Output Gaps ............ 20 The Impulse Responses of Inflations ................... 23 The Impulse Responses of Relative Prices ................ 24 The Impulse Responses of Output Gaps and Inflations ........ 55 The Impulse Responses of Output Gaps with New Monetary Policy Rule 58 The Impulse Responses of Inflations with New Monetary Policy Rule 59 The Impulse Responses to Change of Depreciation Rate (6) ...... 60 The Impulse Responses to Change of Relative Price Stickiness (a) . . 61 Optimal Policy Frontier ......................... 77 Optimal Policy Frontier(DCT) ...................... 79 Sensitivity Analysis of Policy Frontier .................. 80 Sensitivity Analysis of Policy Frontier .................. 81 ix Chapter 1 Optimal Monetary Policy in Two Sector Model 1 . 1 Introduction It is well known that monetary policy can have different consequences across sectors. Housing, consumer durables, and agriculture are often cited as examples of sectors that are sensitive to the change of monetary policy.1 However, in academic literature as well as practice, the diflerent impacts of mon- etary policy on sectors are sometimes ignored under the assumption that society and the central bank have an interest only in aggregated variables such as inflation and output? The following episode illustrates the case that a part of the economy can be influenced severely by the monetary policy which was implemented based on aggregated variables in late 70’s and early 80’s. “Construction workers protesting soaring interest rates on mortgages and construction loans jammed downtown streets here at noontime yesterday with hundreds of pieces of construction equipment. Pickup trucks, cement mixers, backhoes and flatbed trucks carrying bulldozers were part of the protest procession. ------ Jack Scelza, president of the Home Builders lFor surveys of literature on the sectoral impacts of monetary policy actions, see Mann (1969) and Bordo (1980). 2In recent years, New Keynesian models have been increasingly popular for optimal monetary policy analysis. These models have focused on the central bank’s objective to target aggregated vari- ables. See, for example, Clarida, Call and Gertler (1999), Goodfriend and King (1997), McCallum and Nelson (1999), Svensson (1997. 1999, 2002), and \Noodford (1999. 2003). Association of Hartford County, CT, said that housing construction had dropped from 23,500 units a year before the 1974 recession to 14,000 units annually through 1979.”(New York T imes, Apr 10, 1980) This episode tells us that even though overall stabilization policy could be suc- cessful, sectoral impacts may be considerable, so that monetary policy makers should consider sectoral responses and stabilization. It also shows us that agents may care about their own sector’s stabilization rather than the aggregated one. Therefore, one important issue to be addressed is whether it is an appropriate policy goal for the central bank to seek to stabilize only aggregated variables, if people care about the stabilization of their own sector or industry. The purpose of this paper is to answer this question. Specifically, this paper examines the characteristics of desirable monetary policy within a two sector model with durable and nondurable goods sectors. The reason for considering this issue in the context of durable and nondurable goods sectors is that these two sectors seem to show considerably different responses to monetary policy actions. Figure 1.1 plots the (log) real GDP (RGDP), its com- ponents: durable and nondurable goods, the rate of GDP deflater inflation (INF) and the Federal Funds rate (F F R).3 The graph shows that ex post real interest rate is associated with excess volatility of durable goods’ output during early 70’s and 80’s. In other words, this historical data shows that two sectors respond differently to monetary policy action, which is implemented by the change of the Federal Funds rate, and durable goods sector could be influenced more severely. This stylized fact also has been confirmed by related studies (Mankiw (1985), Baxter (1996), Weder (1998)) We also investigate whether the main principles obtained in one good models, such as the “stabilization bias” under pure discretion, still hold in the two goods model. This paper will show that basic principles still hold regardless of the nature of shocks, i.e., whether it is a cost shock or sector specific. In addition, when a central bank’s objective is to minimize deviations of the 3The data runs from 19542Q3 to 2004zQ4 and all GDP series are detrended by HP filter. 20 —— INF —————— FFR 15 s :11 i". 10 4 xi“ "' I i f". "i ‘|' ". {“\ 5 -‘ 1 o [ITT‘TIIITII'1'IITTIEIIITIIII'Vl'Ir‘I'TTrlI'I'ITTEI 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 0.15 0.10 a 0.05 -— /\ t, I 0.00 _."~,".y,._i, ‘,"— x “.7; / 4’ Ll I, I ‘ \JI’ " V I -0.05 _ -0.10 - —— DURABLE ------- NONDURABLE ————— HGDP -0.15 [I'VEIIIEUIUEIUlt't'l‘iTT'l'T'lI‘IIUIII'IIrWIEIT'I' 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 Figure 1.1: The Real GDP, the Inflation Rate and the Federal Funds Rate disaggregated variables from their targets, rather than that of aggregated variables, this paper will argue that, under some circumstances, a central bank should not seek to target the aggregate output gap and inflation, but disaggregated variables. This result leads to the question of what kind of monetary policy rule performs well in the two goods model considered. Simulation results illustrate that it could be optimal to target disaggregated variables.4 Specifically, we consider the strict output gap targeting in which the central bank targets only sectoral output gaps, and durable goods sector targeting in which the central bank targets durable goods’ output gap and inflation only. Finally, we examine the implications of optimal monetary policy when durability and relative price stickiness change. To address above issues, we construct a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with two sectors; durable and nondurable. The model used in this paper is the simplified version of Erceg and Levin (2001). W hile they assume that price as well as nominal wage are sticky, we just assume that only price is sticky. Furthermore they incorporate Taylor(1979) style’s staggered price and nominal wage setting into their model while we introduce Calvo (1983) style’s staggered price setting into the model. They concluded that targeting a weighted average of aggregate wage and price inflation rate is close to the optimal policy outcome. But in this paper we will argue that under discretionary policy, the central bank can obtain benefit from targeting disaggregate inflations and output gaps. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 1.2 we present the basic two sector model, where aggregate demand and supply relations are derived. Section 1.3 presents the method and basic results of simulation. Section 1.4 con- siders the optimal policy rules, where social welfare loss is minimized. Section 1.5 presents the implications of optimal monetary policy when durability and relative price stickiness change. Section 1.6 concludes. 4As to similar approaches, see, for example. Aoki (2001) and Erceg and Levin (2001). 1 .2 The Model 1.2. 1 Households There is a continuum of infinitely—lived individuals, whose total is normalized to unity, and are two different types of goods: nondurable and durable goods. Consumers obtain utility from both nondurable and durable goods. We denote a typical durable good as d and a typical nondurable good as n. The representative household is assumed to have preferences over nondurable goods consumption (Cmt), the service flow from the durable good stock (St), real money balances (gin), and leisure (It). A specific functional form for expected utility is assumed 00 1—1/ 1 I A! I t ,1 I— .- t , Et 2 l3 1_ 001’1,tCt a + 1_ Vt’zi (—Pt) + avatlifi] , (1-1) t=0 ' where Ct is the household’s consumption of a composite consumption good, Alt are the household’s nominal money balances, Pt is the aggregate price index, It is the household’s leisure, x3 is the subjective utility discount factor, 21; is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution of the consumption bundle, 1/ is the elasticity of real money demand, % is the elasticity of marginal disutility of labor supply, and 09’s are disturbances. We normalize total available time for work effort (at) and leisure (It) to one. Then labor supply of the households is given by nt 2 1 — It. The composite consumption good Ct is defined as C, a 07 n,t 83—7, 0 < 7<1, (1.2) where Cn,t denotes the purchase of nondurable goods and St is the service flow of durable stock. The stock of durable consumption goods evolves as follows St+1=(1— (5)5} + Cd.t- 0 < 6 S 1, SO = given, (1.3) where Cdt is the purchase of durable goods in period t, and (5 represents the rate of depreciation. There is a positive initial endowment of the durable stock SO. Equation (1.3) implies that durable goods begin to yield a service flow in the period after the durable good is purchased. Alternatively, we can assume that installation of the durable goods requires one period for stocks.5 CM and Cd.t are assumed as Dixit- Stiglitz aggregates of differentiated products as follows 0 0n _ H“ 1 612—1 ”—1 1 2%} d—l Cn,t: ‘/Ocn,t(3) n (12 7 Cult: /Ocd.t(5) d dz , (14) where Q, for j = n, d is the elasticity of substitution between any different varieties of the differentiated goods. It is also the price elasticity of demand for any single variety of the differentiated goods. It follows from the above specification of preferences that the minimum cost of obtaining a unit of the sectoral composite goods (Cmt and Cd,t) is given by the sectoral price index I 1 1-9,- 1‘9) . Pjt E /0 ])j_t(:) J for j = n,d, (1.5) where pj,t(z) is the price of good .2 in period t and sector 3'. Given the relative size 9 of the nondurable goods sector, the aggregate price index or the general price level Pt is defined as 1— Pt = Prf.th,t 9, O < 9 <1, (1.6) The optimal allocation of demand across the various differentiated goods by con- sumers satisfies .0 (*l 45 cj’t(z) = ( 11ft ) Cj,t forj 2: n,d, (1.7) .79 for each good 2 in sector j . The household’s nominal budget constraint in period t is 5This setting of durable goods is in parallel with the literature on investment decision. In contrast, Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), Startz (1989), and Barsky. House and Kimball (2004) assume that durable goods provide service flow in the same period they are purchased. as follows Pn,tCn,t+Pd,t (St+1 — (I — d)St)+rWt-l-Bt=I'tht+ilft_1+Et+Rt_1Bt_1+TRt, (1.8) where PM and Pd,t denote the price index of nondurable goods and durable goods respectively, hit is nominal money holding for next period, Bt is nominal bond hold- ing for next period, Wt is nominal wage, St is profit, Rt—l is nominal interest rate and is assumed to be the central bank’s interest rate instrument, and TRt is gov- ernment transfer. we assume that complete financial markets exist in the economy. Households are, therefore, able to insure themselves against all types of uncertainty in the model. It follows from this assumption that all households will consume same amounts of the composite consumption goods. Finally, we assume that all distur- bances follow stationary AR(1) processes a)“ = Pj'i'f’jJ—l + fig. 0 S pj < 1, tirjfig 2 given for j = 1, 2,3, (1.9) where innovations {’s have zero means and standard deviations oj for j = 1, 2, 3. In every period t, each household maximizes its expected lifetime utility, with respect to its choice of nondurable consumption (Crag), durable stock (St), real money balances (AI/1%), bonds (Bt), and its labor supply (at), subject to its budget constraint which is denominated by the general price level (Pt). The first order conditions for each choice variable are given by _ P. 71,01,403,th H77) C7 13,1 7 = A, ""t (1.10) 1-0 5(1’7)Et‘r’1 t+1 (Cu t+ISt+1)—a Cu. t+1St+1 Pd,t Pd t+1 /\t— Et [3(1 —5)/\i 1 ’ , U“) P + Pt+1 . _ , P Pt . ,thEtAt+1'1—j_ 2 At, (1.13) t+1 023’t'nt‘ = At?t, (1.14) where At is “Lagrangian multiplier”, the marginal utility of nominal income in period t, 2;; is relative price of sector j denominated by the aggregate price index Pt, mt is real money balances 6%) and Et is the expectations operator conditional upon all information up to period t. Equation (1.10) states the efficiency condition of nondurable goods consumption. Equation (1.11) is the efliciency condition of durable goods services. This intertemporal Euler equation emphasizes that the purchase of a durable good is partly an investment. The equations (1.12), (1.13) and (1.14) show the optimal conditions for money demand, bonds and labor supply respectively. Combining the three Euler equations (1.10), (1.11), and ( 1.13) into one eliminating Cn,t+1 E Lt. (1.15) ,/ _’l’ E livl’2,tSt+1 Pt Pn.t+l _Pd,t (1-5) t[,/, BAH-1] ,/ 7t t , _ _ _ Mac"; Pt+1 Pn.t Pt Rt Pt+1 The variable Lt is defined as the period t rental price, or user cost, of the durable good. Equation (1.15) states that the marginal rate of substitution of nondurables consumption for the service of durables equals the user cost of durables in terms of nondurables consumption. The above equations represent a quite complicated system of stochastic nonlinear difference equations. Therefore, we will loglinearize the above equations around the steady state with zero sectoral inflations and the efficient level, 109097;) for j=n,d, of output gaps. By using a log-linear approximation and steady state conditions with flexible prices, we can derive intertemporal IS equations in both sectors from the above first order conditions. First, the intertemporal IS equation in the nondurable sector is derived from a log—linear approximation of Euler equations, (1.10) and ( 1.13), and from nondurable goods market clearing condition, Yn,t = Cn,t as follows A A A (—07 + 1- 1)Yn.t - (-07+ 7 -1)(1- 5)Yn,t—1 + 5(1- 0)(1- ant—1 = (Rt—fin,t+1)—(1—5)(Rt—1—7in,t)—(00’ - 7 +1)Et [Yn,t+1-(1— AWN] +5(1- 0)(1- ’7')Yd,t - (1 - mil/711+ (1 - p1)(1- 5)’¢’1,t—1v (1-16) or alternatively . 1 . Aymt = _07 + "7' _ lEtaiRt — 7rn,t+1) + EtAYn’t+l 5(1-0)(1-*r) [ . (1-P1) , Y — Y J — A , 1.17 + _0,,, + , _1 d..t d,t—1 -07 + 7 _1 Wu ( ) where X t represents the percent deviation of variable X from its steady state value under flexible prices. The A denotes quasi-difference Xt — (1 — 6)Xt_1. The sectoral Pn,t inflation of nondurable goods sector, any, is defined as The coefficient n,t— $717717 < 0 is related to the rate of intertemporal substitution determining to what extent changes in the real interest rate in terms of nondurable goods, Rt — Et7Tn,t+1a affect spending growth of consumption. Likewise, using the law of motion of durable stock (1.3), the first order condition for durable stock (1.11) and durable goods’ market clearing condition, Yd,t = Cd,t1 we can derive an intertemporal IS equation in the durable goods sector as follows 1 1430—5) Watt = Et AYn,t+1— A(Pt—7Td,t+1)—AP1~,t+1 , (118) where 15731 is defined as the percent deviation of relative price index (figfi) from its steady state value. The above two equations, (1.17) and (1.18), represent the ag- gregate spending relationship, corresponding to a traditional IS equation. Equation (1.17) represents quasi-difference aggregate demand in the nondurable sector depend- ing on its own expected future and current output, lagged and ex ante real interest rate. durable goods’ current and lagged output, and taste shock. Equation (1.18) is the aggregate demand of durable goods sector. The aggregate demand for durable goods depends on the future and current period’s relative price, its own real interest rate (Rt — Etrrd’t +1), and nondurable goods’ output. The reason is that, by defini- tion, the current purchases of durable goods are determined by the difference between future and current period’s durable stock (see eq. (1.3)). In general, the standard results are confirmed in the sense that each sector’s aggregate output depends neg- atively on real interest rate (Rt — jat) for j=n,d, and positively on the one period ahead expected future output in the nondurable goods sector. As a special case, note that if we assume that all goods are totally depreciated in one period, i.e., 6 = 1, the two equations collapse to the traditional two sector intertemporal IS equations. 1.2.2 Firms We assun'ie differentiated goods and monopolistic competition in both final goods markets. The firms use only one variable input: labor. This implies that durable goods are used only in consumption. Labor is assumed to be homogeneous in both sectors and there is no restriction for mobility across sectors. The production tech- nologies are the same in both sectors and operate under a linear technology as follows flitizl = 1(14j,tnt for j = 71,01. (1.19) where 2 represents an individual good producer and Iii/'4,t represents technology shock. The technology shock is assumed to follow a stationary AR(1) process 194$ = P4'1()4,t—1 + £21, 0 S 04 < 1» 204,0 = given: (120) where the innovation {3 has a zero mean and standard deviation (754. However, as Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987) indicate, imperfect competition alone does not generate monetary nonneuturality. For a model to lead to real effects of money, we need to assume the sticky price adjustment. As an essential part of the model, pricing decisions are assumed to be sticky. Specifically, we follow the Calvo- 10 style staggered price setting rule in assuming that in each period a fraction 1 — aj for j: n, d of producers in each sector is offered the opportunity to choose a new price, independent of the length of time since the price was set and of what the particular good’s current price may be, while the remaining producers have to maintain whatever price they charged before. The representative firm’s profit maximization problem is as follows _g —0 00 p. (z) W {P- (Z) Marc E, as) A,, ,,. P.-,,(z) 3’, k— , Y't k 1 Q J ’ + J’ P j,t+k 3’ + it’4,t+k\ P j,t+k 3’ + (1.21) where (aj-B)k/\t,t+k represents a stochastic discount factor. A, is marginal utility of income as we defined in the previous section. The left hand side of the bracket repre— sents the revenue that satisfies the demand condition. Since both goods markets are operated under monopolistic cognpetition, an individual firm producing the product 2 faces the demand, (git—:3) _ JYJ-J +1; for j = n, (1.6 The right hand side represents the nominal cost. The first order condition to maximize profit can be written as 00 , p;, 0 and the output gap enters the loss function. In our simulation, we consider only flerz'ble inflation targeting. 22However, note that simple Taylor rule might not be a global optimal rule because it considers the use of the instrument within restricted parameterizations and variables. 30 Table 1.5: Outcomes of Alternative Delegations Schemes and Optimal Taylor Rule Policy Loss(104) 03;,” 03nd 071-377, 07rd 03; 07; Optimal Weight COM 4.066 1.29 3.76 1.30 1.12 0.94 1.04 - OTR 12.255 1.41 11.67 1.50 1.64 2.96 1.29 A0“ = 0.5, ’\0t2 = 1.4 IT 24.934 1.65 19.34 0.78 2.22 5.48 0.23 x\* = 0.01 OGT 26.728 1.70 20.01 0.75 2.33 5.67 0.19 A09 = 0.01 SGT 6.135 1.22 0.47 1.64 2.52 0.59 1.50 it; = 0.6, it; = 0.01 DGT 7.500 1.71 8.71 1.67 0.42 2.93 1.35 Adg = 0.01 (SGT). Thus, the central bank is given the period loss function LigaT = ”Eighth +fl‘d‘rc21,t+i‘ (1'42) where weights on output gaps (It; and #2) are chosen optimally. Finally, we consider the policy to only target the durable goods sector (DGT), Then the policy objective is given by DGT _ 2 2 Lt — Adgfd,t+i + 7Td,t+i' (143) where weights on output gaps (Adg) is chosen optimally. The first row of Table 1.5 shows outcomes of the optimal precommitment in the benchmark case, which targets sectoral variables and is included for comparison. The other five lows include the case of optimal Taylor rule (OTR), inflation targeting (IT), change in output gap targeting (OGT), strict output gap targeting (SGT) and durable goods sector targeting (DGT), with all preference parameters (A’s and u’s) chosen optimally. The table shows the value of social loss and standard deviations of sectoral and aggregate output gaps and inflations for each policy regime. First, we note that precommitment shows the best outcome in terms of society’s welfare loss. The improvement of the welfare loss ranges from 13 to 140 percent rel- ative to the other optimal discretionary policies, as we interpret the loss in quarterly terms. Second, optimal Taylor rule produces more efficient outcome than other policy regimes that minimize the deviation of aggregate output gap and inflation, while the change in output gap targeting regime results in a poor outcome?3 On the other ”In the similar model we consider in this paper, Erceg and Levin (2002) obtain a very poor 31 hand, the strict output gap targeting and the durable goods sector targeting regimes, which are optimal policies to target disaggregated variables, show more eflicient out- comes than any other policy rcgimes that minimize the deviation of aggregate output gap and inflation. If we look at the standard deviations of variables under various optimal policies, we can infer why optimal policies under the one good model are no longer optimal in the two goods model. For example, while optimal inflation targeting with the weight 0.01 in output gap succeeds to stabilize aggregate inflation relative to precommitment policy, it fails to stabilize the sectoral output gaps, especially the output gap in the durable goods sector. One the other hand, policies to target disaggregated variables succeed to stabilize the fluctuation of durable goods sector even if its share is small.24 That is why the latter results in a more efficient outcome in terms of social welfare loss. In summary, this simulation result shows that it may not be optimal to stabilize the aggregate output gap and inflation through various policy regimes when the society’s true loss depends on disaggregated variables, and suggests that under discretion, optimal policies in the one good model may not hold in multi-sector model. 1.5 The Role of Durability and Relative Price Stick- iness In this section, we examine the role of durability and price stickiness for optimal monetary policy in the two sector model. We saw that durability (6) is one of the most important parameters since it causes non-negligible real interest sensitivity differences in both sectors. Thus it would be interesting to discuss what the implications of optimal monetary policy are, as durability changes. outcome for the inflation targeting regime. But this difference in the result is due to the specification of their policy objective function in which they consider only strict inflation targeting in the sense of Svensson (1997, 1999). Furthermore their price adjustment scheme and nominal wage contract. are built on Taylor-style staggered price setting. 24In our simulation, we assumed that the output of durable goods accounts for 20 percent out of total output. 32 Table 1.6: The Welfare Less (104) of the Change of Durability (5) Policy 6 = 0.1 6 = 0.4 6 = 0.7 5 = 0.99 Precommitment 4.066 4.136 4.356 3.579 IT 24.934 12.561 9.294 9.913 OT 12.255 5.695 6.297 6.774 OGT 26.728 13.427 9.528 9.987 SOT 6.135 6.654 7.156 7.998 DGT 7.500 6.755 10.385 14.399 Table 1.6 shows welfare losses under alternatives policies, as durability changes. First, we note that overall, as durability decreases, that is, the depreciation rate (6) increases, the efficiency of policies improves except for the policies that target disaggregated variables. One possible explanation might be that the fluctuation due to the durability of goods is reduced as they lose their intrinsic aspect, i.e., durability. In particular, optimal Taylor rule achieves the second best outcome when durability is very small. On the other hand, while the strict output gap and durable goods sector targeting regimes do not perform well compered to the policies that care about aggregate variables when durability of goods is low, both policies, especially durable goods sector targeting regime, are strongly recommended in the case of high durability. This fact implies that when the durability of goods leads to the high real interest rate sensitivity difference across two sectors, it is optimal for the central bank to use policies to target disaggregated output gaps or the sector sensitive to real interest rate if precommitment is not feasible. Put another way, in the case that durability introduces sectoral asymmetry into the economy, the policy rules that care about disaggregated variables become more efficient. Until now we have used a baseline value of the degree of price stickiness. So we did not consider the role of the relative price index which is defined as the price index of composite durable goods relative to composite nondurable goods’ one. In recent work, some researchers have focused on the implication of sectoral differences of price adjustment for optimal monetary policy and business cycles.25 In this subsection, 25See, for example, Aoki (2001), Ohanian and Stockman (1994), Barsky, House, and Kimball (2004). 33 Table 1.7: The Welfare Loss (104) of the Change of Relative Price Stickiness (an, ad) Policy (on = 0, ad = 0.36 an = 0, ad = 0.56 I an = 0, ad = 0.86 Precommitment 2.722 4.787 7.859 IT 9.472 25.180 19.676 OT 14.289 46.345 70.824 OGT 9.451 46.955 23.787 SOT 7.951 7.945 7.939 DGT 5.481 8.091 7.937 we consider the implication of sectoral differences of price adjustment for optimal monetary policy. To highlight the result, we assume that prices of the nondurable goods sector are completely flexible, which means that the coefficient of price adjust- ment an is zero. Then we consider the case that the stickiness of price adjustment of durable goods sector changes from a flexible case, i.e., “(120-362 relatively to an almost constant case, i.e., ad=0.86. Table 1.7 shows values of welfare losses under alternative policy regimes when the degree of price adjustment is different across two sectors. First, the level of loss under precommitment increases when the relative price stickiness increases. One possible explanation is that increase in the relative price stickiness introduces an additional loss into the economy. Second, in contrast with the result of the previous section, the optimal Taylor rule performs very poorly while inflation targeting results in lowest welfare loss out of policy regimes that minimize the aggregate variables. This result suggests that conventional policy rules which seek to stabilize aggregated variables are not robust. When the relative price stickiness is high, the simulation result shows that poli- cies to target disaggregated variables lead to lowest welfare losses. Especially, the policy to target durable goods sector which has more sticky price appears to achieve the lowest welfare loss. Targeting durable goods sector inflation with sectoral output gap can be considered as flexible inflation targeting with an objective to minimize sectoral variables rather than aggregate ones, in the sense of Svensson (1997, 1999). When the policy is interpreted like this, the finding is consistent with Aoki (2002) and Benigno (2004). According to Aoki, the optimal monetary policy is to target 34 sticky price inflation in the model with a flexible-price sector and a sticky-price sec- tor. In our model, it is possible for the central bank to obtain optimal outcomes through stabilizing only the durable goods sector, which has high price stickiness, if the precommitment policy is not available. In summary, simulation results show that when fundamental structure of the economy is characterized by multiple-sectors and high relative price stickiness across sectors, it could be an optimal monetary policy for the central bank to stabilize either disaggregated variables or one sector with higher relative price stickiness if precommitment is not available.26 1.6 Conclusion This paper argues that since monetary policy actions can have different effects across sectors, sectoral stabilization is an important issue to address. It also explores the implications and alternative monetary policy rules if people care only about their own sector or industry. Our main conclusions can be summarized as follows. First, simulation results show that traditional principles obtained from one good models still hold in the two sector model considered. Optimal precommitment policy in a New Keynesian one good model features inertial behavior or history dependence. This characteristic contributes to the improvement of the trade-off between inflation and output gap variability through expectations about future inflation. Second, it might be suboptimal for the central bank to target aggregated variables in our model. A critical assumption for this result is that the true social welfare loss function depends on disaggregated output gaps and inflations. We have considered two typical policy regimes under discretion, i.e., inflation targeting and “change” in aggregate output gap targeting and optimal Taylor rule. Simulation results shows that all above policy regimes result in poor outcomes compared to the policy regimes that care about disaggregated variables. 26Even though we did not include the outcome of targeting only nondurable goods sector in the text, it shows very poor outcome. 35 Third, in regard to optimal monetary policy design in the model considered, the strict output gap targeting regime, which targets only the disaggregated output gaps, is a second-best policy rule. In addition, sectoral inflation targeting -in our case, durable goods sector targeting- also performs well. All these results suggest that the stabilization of sectoral output gaps is as important as inflation when each sector responds to the monetary policy instrument differently. . Fourth, the analysis of durability changes shows that the more durable the good is, the more policy should care about sectoral variables. The intuition is as follows: a more durable good means higher real interest rate sensitivity of aggregate demand, so that the fluctuation of output gaps across sectors will show more different patterns of dynamics as a shock hits the economy. As long as society is concerned with the stabilization of sectoral variables, the policy rule to target sectoral variables becomes more efficient. Finally, the analysis of a change in relative stickiness suggests that if precommitment is not possible, it could be optimal to stabilize the sector with the higher relative price stickiness (in our case, durable goods sector). 36 Chapter 2 Two Sector Business Cycle: Durable and Nondurable Goods 2. 1 Introduction One of the main concerns in macroeconomics is the effects of monetary distur- bances on the real economy, in particular the role of money in economic fluctuations. Monetary shocks can have substantial real effects in ” Keyensian” models because this sort of model generally incorporates nominal and/ or real rigidities. However, Chari et al.(1996) argue that the New-Keynesian macroeconomic model developed under sticky price assumption does not generate sufficient price rigidity beyond the exoge- nously imposed period of nominal price or wage stickiness and hence have difficulty in generating a persistent response of output and inflation to monetary shocks. There have been various attempts to solve the ”persistence problem”. For example, Kiley (1997) shows that incorporating real rigidities can increase persistence in the model. Christiano et al. (2001) argue that staggered wage contracts and variable capital utilization can account for the inertia in inflation and persistence in output. Dotsey et al. (1999) argue that three features of the ’supply side’ of the economy: produced inputs, variable capacity utilization, and labor supply variability through changes in employment can help together to dramatically reduce the elasticity of marginal cost with respect to output. Therefore, persistence can be generated. 37 On the other hand, consumer durables are thought to play a central role in the generation and propagation of business cycles. Mankiw( 1985), Baxter(1996), Erecg and Levin (2002), Weder (1998) investigate whether consumer durables are important for the generation and propagation of business cycles. Mankiw argued that under— standing fluctuations in consumer purchases of durables is vital for understanding economic fluctuations. Baxter constructs a two—sector model that succeeds in gener- ating business cycles to investigate whether consumer durables are important for the generation and propagation of business cycles. Weder studies the role of durable goods and sunspots in the generation and propagation of economic fluctuations. Barsky et al. investigate the relationship between durable goods and price stickiness and then Show that the behavior of the model depends on whether durable goods have sticky prices. This study investigates the role of durability to generate the substantial effect of money on output and inflation. Following the strand of New-Keynesian research, price stickiness is introduced into the model so that money has a non-negligible real effect. we construct a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with monopolis- tic competition in the goods market. Specifically, the model consists of two sectors: nondurable goods and durable goods, to focus on the implications of monetary policy when some goods are durable. For analytical tractability, first we consider the case in which durable goods last for only two periods. But the discussion will be extended to the multi-period case later. We will show that durability can change output and inflation dynamics in im- portant ways. This effect happens through two channels. First, since households ob- tain utility from the flow of services durable goods provide, durability causes current marginal utilities and marginal rates of substitution to depend on past and future pur- chases of durable goods. This fact implies that aggregate demand for durable goods are determined by past and expected future purchases as well as current purchases. Furthermore if we assume that nondurable and durable goods are non—separable in utility, durability can affect the nondurable consumption path, that is intratemporal substitution appears. Second, when firms set their optimal price, durability is one 38 of factors they refer to. Thus aggregate price level and inflation dynamics are deter- mined partly by durability of goods. As we will see, inflation dynamics are seriously affected by the rate of depreciation and the number of periods durable goods last. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2.2 constructs the two sector dynamic general equilibrium model and fundamental structural equations are derived. Section 2.3 considers the case that durable goods last more than two periods and discusses the implication of durability to generate the inertia in inflation and persistence in output. Section 2.4 implements simulation and sensitivity analysis. Section 2.5 concludes. 2.2 The Model 2.2. 1 Households The economy is composed of a continuum of infinitely—lived individuals, whose total is normalized to unity. Consumers obtain utility from both nondurable goods and durable goods. We denote a typical durable good as d and a typical nondurable good as n. The representative household is assumed to have preferences over non- durable goods consumption (Cm): the service flow from the durable good stock (St), real money balances (9%) and leisure (It). A specific functional form for expected utility is assumed oo 1_ EtZfit —1-—wl 01—0, 1 2t 5“- V+-1-u> (I—IW (21) 1—0 ’t t 1—1/“2’t Pt ¢ 3’t t ’ ’ t—O where g— is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution of the consumption bundle, % is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution of leisure and fl is the utility discount factor. The 112’s are disturbances in each argument. All disturbances are assumed to follow stationary processes. The consumption bundle Ct is given by a Cobb-Douglas functional form, C, a (37 33—7, (2.2) mt 39 where Cn,t is the consumption of nondurable goods and St is the durable stock. For an analytical solution, the durable stock lasts for only two periods. Thus the stock of durable consumption goods evolves as follows: St = (1— (”Cit—1 + Cit? 0 < (l S 1 (2.3) where Cd.t is the purchase of durable goods in period t and the (5 represents the rate of depreciation. Cm and C,“ are assumed as Dixit-Stiglitz aggregates of differentiated products as follows 9 6 1 9%: #1 1 9,11 9.1-1 Cmt: focnfiz) 'n dz . Q“: /Ocd,t(2) d dz , (2.4) where Bj for j = n, d is the elasticity of substitution between any different variety of the differentiated goods. It is also the price elasticity of demand for any single variety of the differentiated goods. It follows from the above specification of preferences that the minimum cost of obtaining a unit of the sectoral composite goods (CW and Cd,t) is given by the sectoral price index: 1 1 1_9 m . Pj,t E [0 pj’t(z) for] = n,d (2.5) The optimal allocation of demand across the various differentiated goods by con- sumers satisfies p- ("l 4)]. Cjt = J’t ~ Cj.t for j = n,d, (2.6) : Pj,t . for each good 2 in sector j. The household’s nominal budget constraint in period t is as follows, Pn.tC‘n..t + Pd,th,t + [lift + Bt = ll"7tnt+ll'[t_1 + Et + Rt—lBt—l + TRt (2.7) 40 where Pn,t and Pd,t denote the price index of nondurable goods and durable goods respectively, Mt is nominal money holding for next period, Bt is nominal bond holding for next period, Wt is nominal wage, St is profit, Rt_1 is nominal interest rate of previous period, and TRt is government transfer. In every period t, each household maximizes its expected lifetime utility, eq. (2.1) with respect to its choice of nondurable consumption, durable stock, real money balances, bonds and its labor supply: subject to its budget constraint, eq.(2.7). The budget constraint is denominated by general price level (Pt) as defined properly. The first order conditions for each choice variable are given by .. , 1— —1 (1—7)(1-0) P .t ’7’t“’1,tC;,(t 0’ [(1 - 5)Cd,t—1 + Cd,t] = M72:- (28) PdJ 7(1— 0) (1‘7)(1—0)-1 a7? =(1—w>w.1tC,., [<1— 6>C.1,._1+ Cat] '71(— a) (1—7)(1—0)-1 +13(1—5)(1—7)E,z.;-1.,+IC,{,H [(1—5)Cd,,+cd,,+1] (2.9) Alt , P t‘2,t (fit—V) — /\t - /3Et/\t+lp;:—l— (2.10) _ IV um"? I = M735: (2'11) , P At = (3RtEt/\t+1rp_t, (2-12) t+1 where At denotes the marginal utility of nominal income in period t and (1:25;) rep- resents relative price of sector 2' denominated by Pt. Equation (2.8) states the effi- ciency condition of nondurable goods consumption. Equation (2.9) is the condition of durable goods services. Since we assumed that the durable stock lasts for only two periods, only two periods of marginal utility terms are considered in the left hand side of equation (2.9). Equations (2.10), (2.11) and (2.12) show the optimality conditions for money demand, labor supply and bonds respectively. By using a log-linear approximatirm and steady state conditions with flexible 41 prices, we can derive intertemporal IS equations in both sectors from the above first order conditions. X represents the percent deviation of variable X from its steady state value under flexible prices. Yn,t = EtYn,t+1 — (1’1 [(1 - CAI/at + EtAi/d,t+1] —(I>2Et [(Rt — 7ft) — Ain,t+1 + AIZ’I,t+1] (1-7)(1-C) q, = 1 1-70-0)’ 2 1-70-01 where (D1 = (2.13) I’d): = EtYd,t+1+‘1>3[AYd,t+BEtAYd,t+2 -‘1’4Et [AYn,t+1+fi(1-5)AYn,t+2l 4’5 [Et (Rt - 7Tt+1) - EtAid,t+1l - (I’GEt [A¢1,t+1+fi(1-5)A¢1,t+2j _ 1—5 <1» _ y(1——0)(1+(1—-6)) — 2. 4 — , 2 , . 1+fi(1—5) (1+/3(1-6) )(1-7(1—0)) = (1+ fi(1 - 5))(l + (1 - 6)) 5 (1+M1—eau—vu—o»’ (1 + (1 — 6)) 1+ ,{3(1 — 6)?)(1— 7(1— 0)). where (P3 (D6 = (2.14) ( The above two equations represent the aggregate spending relationship, correspond- ing to a traditional IS function. Eq. (2.13) represents aggregate demand in the nondurable sector while Eq. (2.14) is the aggregate demand of durable goods sector. The standard results are confirmed in the sense that each sector’s aggregate output depends negatively on real interest rate (Rt — Wmt) and positively on the one period ahead expected future own output gap. Because we consider two sectors, relative price (133$) is included as an argument. The key result of the model is that current purchases of the two goods depend on past and expected future purchases. In other words, the model generates persistent dynamics of output by including the past output gaps of the durable goods sector. This relationship is due to durability of one good. Because households obtain the utility of the flow of services over two periods from durable goods, the current pur- chase decision of durable goods affects purchases of both goods in the next period. Note that if we assumed all goods totaly depreciated in one period ((5 = 1), the above 42 two equations collapse to the traditional two sector IS equations. 2.2.2 Firms Differentiated goods and monopolistic competition are assumed. The firms use only one variable input: labor. This implies that durable goods are used only in consumption. Labor is assumed to be homogeneous in both sectors. The production technologies are the same in both sectors and operate under a linear technology as follows: yj’t(z) = ”$4”,th forj = n,d. (2.15) where 2 represents an individual good producer. #243“ represents a technology shock. The technology shock is assumed to follow stationary processes. As an essential part of the model, firms’ price setting decisions are assumed to be sticky. Specifically, we follow the Calvo—style staggered price setting rule in assuming that in each period a fraction 1 — aj for j: n, d of producers in each sector is offered the opportunity to choose a new price, independent of the length of time since the price was set and of what the particular good’s current price may be, while the remaining producers have to maintain whichever price they charged before. A firm’s profit maximization problem is _g,. _9. 00 P- (2) J w {P- (z) 2 , k at t+k ,t MaxEt 0'13) AH k P‘t(2) Y'.t k—I Y't k E J ’+ 3’ Pj,t+k 3" + W4,t+k\Pj,t+k 3’ + (2.16) where (aj [3)“At,t+ k represents a stochastic discount factor. The At is marginal utility of income as defined in the previous section. The left hand side of the bracket rep- resents the revenue which satisfies the demand condition. Since the goods market is operated under monopolistic competition, an individual firm producing the product 19100—6. .2 faces the demand, Pl’_ I/ .. for ' = n, d. The ri ht hand side re resents the j,t+k “H” J g p 43 nominal cost. The first order condition to maximize profit can be written as 0- w, k P-.t(z) — J + (2.17) 3' 9) — 1w4,t+k t(Z) Et 2(0’ 0.7/3) kAt t+k (Pjit 6ij¢+k .7: k_ 0 t+k According to the above condition, each firm sets its price Pj’l‘t(z) equal to a markup 0 . ME y—é-f) over its nominal marginal cost. This is the standard result in a model of .7 monopolistic competition. Because the adjusting firms were selected randomly from among all firms in period t—I, the average price in period t satisfies Pj,t = (1P?— jt-— 1 + (1 — a)Pj,t for J = n,d. (2.18) Two equations (2.17), (2.18) can be approximated around a zero average inflation steady state equilibrium to derive the New-Keyensian Phillips curve. By using a log- linear approximation and the definition of each sector’s price level index, we can derive the aggregate supply equation or New—Keynesian Phillips curve for each sector.1 1 ”Tut = [$1 (Yn‘t — Ygt) — K2 2(1 _ 6)] (Yd,t—j - Ygt-j) i=0 _n3 (£3th — 555$) + fiEth,t+l (2.19) where K1 = (l—an)(1-anfi)(¢- (1—0)) 01n(1+6n(¢" 1)) ’ _ (l-an)(1—anfi)(1— v)(1—C) “2 ‘ an(1+6n(¢— 1)) ’ n3 = (1—an)(1—anfi) an(1+ 912025 — 1)). where X n denotes percent deviation from variable X ’s steady state under flexible price. The output gap is defined as YTM ——l77?t. The above equation expresses inflation in the nondurable sector as a function of its sectoral output gap (Yet — 177%), the other sector’s output gap (17,” — 175%), relative price gap (jimt — if: t) and expected 1For detailed derivation of aggregate supply equations, see Appendix A. 44 future inflation. Since two goods are non-separable in utility and durable stocks last for only two periods, the durable good’s output gap is included in this equation. While high aggregate output increases inflation in that sector, relative price (@t—t) decreases inflation in that sector. Note that with complete depreciation (621) the above equation is the same as conventional two sector aggregate supply equations. ”at = N4 (Yet-lift) + K5 [(Yd.t—1 - 3221-1) - fiEt (Yd.t+1 - Ydrft+1)] 1 7‘6: 53(1—6let(Yn,t+j ‘ Yritt+j> ’“3(5€d,t 43%) +3Et7rd,t+1 (2.20) 3:0 when, ,, z (l—O‘dlil“'9'de—(1—7")(1-0))(1+5(1‘5)2) '4 ad(1+ 66(6 - 1))(1+ 60— 6)) ’ <1— 6.1m — 6.1mm — 7(1- 6))(1— 6) ad(1+ 9.1(6 — 1))(1+ 60— 6)) K = (1- Odlfl - ad6)7(1 ‘- 0) '6 ad(1+ 9d(d> — 1)(1+ 60— 6)) The durable goods sector’s inflation looks more complex. But we can notice that the number of lagged and lead output gaps depends on the numberof period’s the durable goods lasts. Durable good inflation dynamics are determined by two sector output gaps, relative prices and expected future inflation. The impact of its output gap and expected inflation, a positive effect, is the same as conventional N ew- Keynesian business cycle models. Because durable goods purchased in the current period depreciate totally after two periods, purchase decisions made last period affect the current purchase decision. Suppliers consider this fact when they decide on their product price. That is why the aggregate durable goods supply equation includes the lagged aggregate outputs by length of durability. Also when the rate of depreciation increases, the coefficient n4 increases whereas n5 decreases. This implies that as durable goods deteriorate more rapidly, the persistent effect of output on inflation decreases. These equations are different from the conventional New—Keynesian Phillips curve 45 in two ways. First, when price stickiness is not same across sectors, relative price fluctuation becomes another transmission mechanism, which does not exist in a one good model. In the face of an unexpected monetary shock and change of relative prices, households and firms adjust their optimization behavior. In fact, the pressure of relative prices reduce the inflationary effect in that sector because of substitution between two goods. Second, durability generates non-negligible endogenous dynamics for sectoral inflations. Since durability introduces time non-separability in the utility function into the model, durability provides the model with substantial persistence. Therefore, this assumption can help to explain a persistent output effect on inflation. But one problem with this model is that it does not show the persistent inflation dynamics in the sense that inflation does not incorporate own past inflation. Because we assumed that firms’ pricing setting decisions are based on only expected future variation of marginal revenue and cost with currently available information, their own expected future product price and aggregate conditions matter. Thus there is no room for past inflations to go into this model like some New-Keynesian literature. 2.3 Multi—Periods Case Since our interest is in the role of durability for substantial real effects of monetary policy, we need to look into implications of durability in more detail. To do this, we extend the periods the goods lasts and then investigate how output and inflation dynamics change. For analytical purpose, in this section we consider the case in which durable goods last for three periods. Then we will extend it to more general N-periods case. 2.3.1 Three Periods Case Let us assume that the purchased durable goods lasts for three periods. Then durable stock evolves as follows: St = <1 — 6)2Cd,t..2 + <1 — 6)C.),._1 + Cd,t (2.21) 46 Except for the evolution of the durable stock, the other components of the model are the same as before. We apply the same steps we used to derive aggregate demand and supply equations in the two period case to the three period case as well. We can obtain output and inflation dynamics in the case that the durable good lasts for three periods as follows: 2.3.2 Aggregate Demand and Supply Equation Because the functional form of aggregate demand is almost the same as previous case, we omit the aggregate demand equations. Instead, we report aggregate supply equations. 2 m, = K, (YE, -— Ygft) — fig 230— 6)] (Yd,t— j " Yalft—j) '=0 —K.3 (ilet — 533$) + fiEtW-n,t+l (2.22) (1 — an)(1 - an.3)(¢ - 7’0 - 0)) where K1 = 0171(1 + 67201) _ 1)) , K = (l—anXl—anfiXl-VXI—a) 2 an(1+ 07m — 1)) n __ (l—an)(1—anfl) 3 " an(1+6n(6—1))' Eq.(2.22) represents the dynamics of inflation in the nondurable goods sector when durable goods last for three periods. Compared to the two periods case, the sectoral inflation depends on more lagged durable sector’s output gaps and has the same coef- ficients of its argument as before. But in the case of durable goods sector, coefficients 47 of variables are different as durability changes as below, 7Id,t = “4(Yd,t_l>£t)+"5[(1+/3(1‘6)2)(Yd,t—1“IA/(12-1)+(1'6)(Yd,t—2—Ydr:t_2) +/’3(1+/3(1-5)2)Et(yd,t+1-Y£t+1)+l32(1_")Et(Yd»t+2_’>£t+2)l 2 46 2: [31(1 —5)JE, (Yth—Ygfij) — n3 (ed,,—5:g,,) + sandy +1(2.23) '=0 (1—0‘d)(1-a'd/3)(¢-(1-7)(1-0))(1+B(1—5)+52(1-5)4) “here “4 _ ad(1+6d(d>—1))(1+fl(1—6)+[32(1—6)2) ’ K = (1-ad)(1-adfl)(1-(1-7)(1-0))(1-5) 5 ad(1+ 6..)(6 — me + 60— 6) + fi2(1 — 6)2)’ ,6 z (l—adxl—adahu—o) aa<1+ 64(6 —- 1)((1+/3(1— 6) + 62(1 — 6)?) Equation (2.23) show that durable good sector inflation is determined by the same arguments as in the two period case. The number of lagged output gaps equal to durability show up in the equation. Therefore, it is confirmed that higher durability causes inflation to depend on longer periods of aggregate output gaps. While the change of the durable sector aggregate output gap is related to inflation positively, the change of the nondurable sector aggregate output gap is related to that of the durable goods sector negatively because of substitution. The sensitivity analysis of the response of coefficients of current aggregate output gaps shows how the impact of own current aggregate output gap (K4) changes by durability compared to the coefficients of two period case. The impact of current aggregate output gaps on inflation decreases as durability becomes longer. 2.3.3' N-Period Case Now we generalize the period of durability to N-periods case. Even though we have difficulty in interpreting the implication of coefficients, there is an advantage to obtain general understanding how durability changes inflation dynamics in important 48 ways. The durable stock in period t evolves as follows: N— =jZ(1—6)10d,_j_., (2.24) Because the derivation procedure of aggregate demand and supply is the same as before, we drop the steps. Instead, we report the result here. Eq. (2.25) represents nondurable good sector’s aggregate supply in the case of N-period case. N—1 7Tn,t = K1 (Yn,t — Yrift) - "2 Z (1 — 5)] (Yet—2' ‘ Yclit—j) i=0 _,.3 (6...: — 6.2,.) + 61616....“ (2.25) where the parameters H’s are the same as before. As we expected, the sectoral inflation is affected by durability of durable goods. The degree of output gap persistence on sectoral inflation, which is defined as the number of lagged and lead output gaps, exactly depends on the number of periods durable goods provide a service flow. But notice that only past aggregate durable good output gaps can affect the nondurable goods sector inflation dynamics. As will see, this result does not apply to durable goods sector case. Eq.(2.26) represents the durable good sector inflation as follow: q —1 71¢, =n3 2 611—6)” (ray—173,) (2.26) '=0 N—l . (N—l—z' . , +n4 Z (1 — 6)’ Z 33(1 - (5)23 (YdJ-i - Ydjt—i) i=1 _ j=1 N—l _ . N—l—i +I~t4 2 62(1 — 6)z fij(15)2j Et (yd,t+i _ Y£t+i> i 1 j=1 N . . —54 Z (3](1 — 5)] Et (Yn,t+j — 37731“) r “‘1 (idj — 63,1) + (3Et71d,t+1) "=0 49 l—ad (I—adfixas—(l—vxl-a» ad (1+ 9d(¢ — 1)) 23:31 6111— 6)J' ’ 1— ad (1— adfi)(1 — (1 — 1x1 — 6)) ad (1+9.)(6 —1))2,; 0151(61— )' where K3 = K4: As we can see, durability can affect inflation dynamics in the same way in the case of the nondurable sector. But in contrast to nondurable sector, its own output gaps are included in the equation. Because durable goods provide a flow of service for N-periods, current purchase is determined by expected future marginal valuation of durable goods. Then suppliers of durable goods incorporate this fact as they set their product price. As a result, durable goods sector inflation includes the past and future output gaps as components by the length of durability. 2.4 Simulation 2.4. 1 Stylized Facts In this section, we simulate the model and conduct sensitivity analysis. Before we simulate the model, we need to discuss some stylized facts about the business cycle. In particular, because we focus on the role of durability in the context of New-Keynesian business cycle model, we summarize some regularities about durable and nondurable goods. For more extensive stylized facts, see Stock and Watson(1999) and King and Rebelo (1999). It is well known that consumption of nondurable goods is less volatile than output. In contrast, consumption of durable goods is strongly procyclical and is more cyclically volatile than real GDP or the other consumption measures. For nominal variables, the price level is countercyclical, but rates of inflation of prices, for example the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and the GDP deflator, are procyclical and lag the business cycle. Nominal interest rates are contemporaneously procycli- cal. Finally, all macroeconomic aggregates display substantial persistence. We will investigate whether durability can generate volatility, persistence and comovement of sectoral and aggregate outputs and inflations. 50 2.4.2 Monetary Policy To close the model, we need to add the monetary policy rule of a central bank to the structural model. Much recent literature has addressed the question of the type of policy rule to which a central bank should commit itself by asking which rule would be the best within some parametric family 0f simple rules. The most famous of such instrument rules is the Taylor rule. Taylor (1993) showed that the behavior of the federal funds interest in the Unite States from the mid-19803 through 1992 could be fairly well matched by a simple rule of the form T) Rt = CUlClit + 072(7Tt —- 7T + 7'* + Q, T was the target level of average inflation, r* was the equilibrium real rate where 7r of interest rate and :IIt was the output gap which is defined as the difference‘between actual output and flexible price equilibrium output. In this simulation, we use a variation of the Taylor rule because we consider two sectors. Specifically, we assume that target output gap and inflation are zero and the central bank commits to the following monetary policy rule, R, = 0.5 (66",, + 6rd,) + 2 (Mt + 7rd,) + ct, (2.27) where subscripts, n and (1 represent the nondurable sector and durable sector re- spectively. The random variable, ct represents an exogenous monetary policy shock. Recently, many economists have argued that the federal funds rate has been the core monetary policy instrument in the US. and also suggest that unforecasted changes in the federal funds rate may provide good estimates of policy shocks. This view has been argued by the ”structural VAR” literature on the identification of monetary policy shocks, for example Bernanke and Blinder (1992) and Sims, Leeper, and Zha (1996). So following this practice, we assume that monetary policy shock can be identified with movements in the Federal funds rate that cannot be predicted given information. According to the above policy rule, the central bank responds to sec- 51 toral output gaps and inflations instead of aggregate output gap and inflation. Like the Taylor rule, the central bank responds to sectoral inflations more aggressively. Specific coefficient value of output gap ranges from .18 to .99, that of inflation ranges from 1.5 to 2.15 in the literature. Here as a base line case, we choose the response coefficient of output gap as .5 and that of inflation as 2. We will consider the case in which the central bank responds to the two sectors differently later. Now we have a complete structural model to implement quantitative analysis. The complete model consists of sectoral demand and supply equations, and the central bank’s monetary policy rule. Also we define aggregate output as the sum of two sector’s output, that is, Yt = Yn,t + Yd,t- Aggregate price index, Pt, is defined as the weighted sum of sectoral price indexes, that is, Pt 2 YnP,” + Yde,t where Yn, Yd are steady state level of output in each sector. For convenience we rewrite the complete model as follows: .. , 1— —1 (1-“')(1-0) P .t 1"W1,tCri.(t 0’ [(1 - 6)Cd.t—1 + Cd,t] I = 61—73,— (228) P(Lt , 7(1—0) (1"?)(1—0l—1 At—P; = (1 — 7)’U11,tCn,t [(1 — 6)Cd,t_1 + Ca] , 1— (l-m)(1-0)—1 + 6(1— 7’)Et1¢1’1,t+1C;/,,(t+10) [(1 — 5)Cd,t + 0.1.11.1] ’ (2.29) P /\t = fiRtEtAtHF-t-s (2-30) t+1 7Tn,t = "31 (Yn,t " Yritt) _ K2 (Yd,t—1 — Yalft—l) — K3 (Yd,t — Yclft) ~K4 (336,1 - flit) + fiEth,t+1 (2-31) 52 716.: = K5 (Yd.t - Kit) + “'6 [(th6—1 — Vii—1) ‘ (’Et (YdatH ‘ Y£t+lll A 1 _,.,7 2 [33(1 — 6)] Et (Ynjfl' _ Ygtfl’) i=0 —).<4 (em—6:3,) +13Et7rd3t+1 (2.32) Rt : 0'5I7Lt + 0'5Id,t + 2701.1 + 271,“ + Q, (2.33) . Yn . Yd . Yt = 7 n,t + 71”,”, (2.34) 7ft = YnIn (”mt + int—1) + ded (7rd,t + field—1) . (2.35) where all 2 represents the percent deviation from their steady state values. Eqs.(2.28) to (2.30) are aggregate demand equations where A is Lagrange multiplier. At equi- librium, Cm = 1’",me = Yd.t- Eq.(2.31) and (2.32) represent sectoral supply equations where the coefficients KS are nonlinear functions of structural parameters. Eq.(2.33) is the monetary policy rule where ct is monetary policy shock. Eqs.(2.34) and (2.35) are derived from the definitions of total aggregate output and the general price index. Next, we need to choose the length of period and structural parameters for the model economy, The length of a model period is one quarter, and the discount factor, [3, is set to .99. The parameter 0 which is the inverse of elasticity of intertemporal substitution, is set to .16. The leisure preference parameter, (I) is 2.5, the preference weight parameter of durable and nondurable goods, 7 is .85. The quarterly depre- ciation rate of the durable stock 6 = .025, consistent with an annual depreciation rate of 10 percent. The price markup parameter, 6, is assumed to be the same across sectors and is set to mag, = 1.15), which means that an average markup in the goods market is 15%. We assume that an average fixed price duration, 0, is .56. As the base line, we consider the case that durable goods last for only two periods. The responses are those to a 1% innovatirm in ct. 2.4.3 Main Results Figure 2.1 shows the impulse responses of output gaps and inflations to a one standard deviation innovation to the monetary policy shock when durable goods have different durability. In the figure, the “yo” represents the dynamics of output gap when there is no durability and the “yg” the dynamics of output gap when durability is two periods and so on. The first panel shows the dynamics of output gaps where the effects of a shock last for about 10 quarters. Even though the initial responses to the monetary policy shock are different over durabilities, the convergence to the steady state level shows almost identical patterns and the effect of the shock disappears after 10 quarters. In other word, durability does not improve the persistence in the case of the output gap. One reason for the result could be as follows. By using eq. (2.28) to (2.30), for convenience, we rewrite eq.(2.13) and (2.14) as follows: YTLJ : EtYn,t+l — (1’1 [(1 - 6)AYd,t—l + EtAYd3t+1] r¢2Et [(Rt — 710- Aim“ + A631¢+1l , Yd,t = EtYd,t+1+‘I’3 [AYd,t+3EtAYd,t+2]—¢4Et [Ayn,t+1+/3(1—6)Ai/n,t+2] 4’5 (E: (Rt - 7111+1) - EtAde¢+1l — ‘PsEt [Aw1,t+1+fi(1—5)Aw1,t+2l - where (D’s are nonlinear functions of structural parameters. As we can see, the output gap of each sector is expressed by differences of lagged own variables, real interest rate and relative prices. These differences may offset the effect of the monetary policy shock on output dynamics. The second panel of Figure 2.1 shows the dynamics of inflations in response to the shock. As we can see, in this case the durability generates more persistent inflation dynamics. With no durability, initial impact is lowest and then goes to the steady state level. As durability increases, the initial impact and the periods the shock lasts increase. In particular, when the durability is four periods, the initial impact decreases to .07 percent and even decreases for two quarters and then goes to the 54 Impulse Responses of Output Gap o . ,2..- ._____ . - --._-__...--- .. {1" 3-- ---- yo -0.1 ,/’I — Y2 _ v3 . W y4 -0.2 _ -0.3 _ -0.4 .. -O.5 _ -0.6 ’- —( -o_7 l J 1 1 1 0 S 10 15 20 25 30 Impulse Responses of Inflation 0 v _ , L ,_.,..,..u.m..__ ”-3.1295417" — _4,_,. ---4--- '"‘ ---- info 4) 01 '/ — ir"2 t _ - - - inf3 '0-02 , -_ inf‘ a —o.03 - -0.04 .. ‘0.05 —( ~0-06 _ .0-07 - -0.08 .. .009 l 1 1 l 1 0 S 10 15 20 25 30 Figure 2.1: The Impulse Responses of Output Gaps and Inflations steady state more slowly. We can notice that as durability increases, the amplitude and persistence of inflation increases. Durability contributes to generate substantial inflation dynamics in this case. The stylized facts say that durable consumption accounts for about 1500 of total consumption and the durable goods sector is more volatile than nondurable goods sector. Because the portion of nondurable goods is greater than that of durable goods in total consumption, it is natural to assume that the central bank responds to the nondurable goods sector more aggressively. If we assume that the central bank put more a weight on the nondurable goods sector, for example .85, then monetary policy rule could be written as follows: Rt 2 0-425113n,t + 0-0754’7d,t + 267m + 27rd,t- (2.36) One the other hand, let us suppose that the central bank responds more aggressively to the volatile sector. The specific monetary policy reaction function is assumed to be Rt = 0-3In,t + 0.717,” + 175701.15 + 2.2571,”. (2.37) According to the above monetary policy reaction function, the central bank puts a higher weight on the durable goods sector to stabilize the economy. In the face of uncontrolled positive monetary policy shock, when the output gap and inflation in the durable goods sector increase given output gap and inflation in the nondurable sector, the central bank increases the nominal interest rate more than in the opposite case. Figure 2.2 shows impulse responses of output gaps and inflation when the central bank uses the adjusted new monetary policy rule to the monetary policy shock where the “112 base” represents the output gap under the base line monetary policy rule and two periods of durability and “y2 wgt” is impulse response under the monetary policy rule, eq (2.36), and so on. The first. three panels compare the varicms monetary policies 56 on output. In the case of two and three periods of durability, the output impulses with the monetary policy rule, one which puts more weight on the nondurable goods sector are greater than other two cases. But when the durability is extended to four periods, there is no significant difference over the monetary policies. When durability is short relatively, the policy rule which puts more weight on the durable goods sector is more effective in the sense that output’s fluctuation decreases. The stabilizing effect appears in the inflation dynamics more dramatically (Fig 2.3). In the case of two and three periods of durability, the effect of the monetary policy rule which puts more weight on the nondurable goods sector on inflation is substantial. When the durability is four, the policy rule which puts more weight on the durable goods sector stabilizes inflation. In this experiment, we can notice that as durability is longer, the weighted new policy, which puts higher weight on the durable goods sector, is more efficient than the base line policy in the sense that the new monetary policy rule stabilizes the economy more than the base line monetary policy and one puts more weight on the nondurable goods sector. 2.4.4 Sensitivity Analysis In this model, the rate of depreciation(6)plays a role in generating persistence in output and inertia in inflation. To investigate the other implications of the model. we change the rate of depreciation (6) to study how the model responds. The default value was 10%. So base line value of 6 is set to .1 and then we would change it to .3, .5, and .7 respectively. Figure 2.4 shows the responses of output gaps and inflations to this experiment where “yol” represents the dynamics of output gap when 6 = .1 and two periods of durability. As we can see, output gaps do not respond to variation in the depreciation rate. Initially, output gaps decrease to about 3.3 percent from their steady state level. The effect of shocks disappear after about ten quarters. On the other hand, inflations show small differences over the change of the parameter. The initial impact depends on the rate of depreciation and converges to steady state level proportionally. We can notice that the higher rate of depreciation leads to weak deviation 96 deviation 9% deviation °/o -O.1 v0.2 -O.3 o0.4 -0.5 '0.6 -O.7 -0.8 o0.9 -0.06 -0.1 -0.16 ~02 -0.26 ~O.3 -035 -0.05 -0. 1 -0.15 —0.2 -O.26 -O 3 -O.36 .04 43.45 -0.5 quarters - - - - yzbeso —— yzwgt _ yznew .1, _ i- n: 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 matters JF - - - - yabaso — Yaw __ yam -( 1 .4 1 ..( , . . . quarters O 5 1O 15 20 25 30 was ":::;:~:T::”“""-T ---- y‘baso -— Y4W9‘ __ y‘new 7 o 5 10 15 20 25 30 Figure 2.2: The Impulse Responses of Output Gaps with New l\1‘lonetary Policy Rule 58 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 deviation -0.05 ‘70 30 - - - - infabaso i -o oos —— unfawgt inf3new -0.01 .0015 -0.02 -0.025 deviation -0.03 °/o -0.035 .004 . . - . lnY‘bOSO — inf‘wot H _. inf‘now -0.01 43.02 -0.03 v0.04 -0.05 deviation 60.08 °/o .0.07 - 4 '0-09 '- ‘\J-’ -( -o 09 A A 1 m l 0 5 1 0 1 5 20 25 30 quarters Figure 2.3: The Impulse Responses of Inflations with New Monetary Policy Rule 59 deviation °/o deviation °/o 0 0'1)- 10 -0-005 .001 .0015 .002 L1 .0025 )- .o.03 ( -0-035 I -o.04 )- -0.045 30 Figure 2.4: The Impulse Responses to Change of Depreciation Rate (6) quarters 60 20 30 -O.1 '0-2 .1 .( C O '; -0.3)- a .9 > 0 ~01! '0 -O.5 P - o\° -O.6 - - 25 30 an inf36 i __ infsfi __ inf76 c: O ; I '1: ': 113 : > 3, ‘ 0 : u 3 , o -0.08 -; 5’ - o\ '- 5 4-1 )- 3. —( -o.12 I 1 I l L 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 quarters Figure 2.5: The Impulse Responses to Change of Relative Price Stickiness (a) 61 initial impact and small response to the convergent path. When we simulate the model, we assumed that both sectors have the same degree of price stickiness, in our model. a. The parameter a represents a fraction of producers in both sectors which is not offered the opportunity to choose a new price in each period. As a base line case. we pick up an and 01d as .66 following Rotemberg and Woodford ( 1997). To incorporate the effect of differences in price stickiness, we choose the parameter value of durable goods sector, ad as .36, .56 and .76 with on = .36 fixed which means that the price stickiness in the durable goods sector increases relative to that in the nondurable sector. Figure 2.5 plots the responses of output gaps and inflations over variation in price stickiness where 3156 represents the output gap when on = .36 and ad = .56 and so on. Figure 2.5 illustrates that output gaps do not show substantial differences, but inflations respond to the monetary policy shocks more persistently as relative price stickiness increases. For example, in the case that on = .36 and ad = .76, the effect of the shocks lasts beyond 25 quarters. In summary, we have investigated the dynamics of sectoral and total output gaps and inflation as durability changes. Durability is not successful in generating the persistent and substantial responses of output gaps except for in the durable goods sector. However we have shown that the persistence of inflation depends importantly on durability of goods. As durability increases, the effect of monetary policy shocks over inflation is more persistent and substantial. Also we have recognized that a change in relative price stickiness can affect the dynamics of inflation rather than output gaps. As relative price stickiness increases, inflations become more persistent and initial impacts of the monetary policy shock decreases. 2.5 Conclusion We considered the role of durability to explain the substantial real effect of money in the context of New-Keynesian model. Our main conclusions can be summarized as follows. First, durability changes aggregate demand in important ways. Because of the intrinsic characteristic of durable goods, the persistence of output gaps is 62 generated by the number of periods durable goods endure in addition to conventional arguments. As durability increases, the persistent effect of output gaps increases. Also the rate of depreciation is correlated with output persistence negatively. Second, when durability of goods is incorporated into the price setting decision, aggregate supply equations depend on both past and expected future output gaps of durable goods. But one difference is that while nondurable goods sector inflation includes only lagged output gaps of durable goods, durable goods sector inflation has both past and expected future own output gaps as its arguments. It implies that the two sectors would respond to monetary policy differently. Therefore, in contrast to the one good model, when policy makers design any optimal monetary policy rule, they should recognize that each sector could respond to policy differently and thus result in unexpected policy outcomes. Finally, even if we consider durable goods, it does not generate persistent inflation dynamics in a sense that inflation does not include any past inflations. 63 Chapter 3 Econometric Policy Evaluation in Two Sector Model 3.1 Introduction Over the past 40 years, economic activity and inflation have become less volatile in the US.1 This “lower volatility” in macroeconomic variables appears to be associated with improved monetary policy (Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000), Cecchetti, Flores- Lagunes, and Krause (2004), Boivin and Giannoni (2003)).2 But even if we agree with the argument, that is, monetary policy has successfully reduced the variance of economic activity and inflation, whether the monetary policy was “optimal” or not is an additional issue to be addressed. On the other hand, it is well known that monetary policy can have different consequences across sectors. However, the recent discussion about the optimal monetary policy has often ignored the sectoral impacts of monetary policy actions since aggregate inflation and output are thought to be main policy concerns. The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the optimality of monetary policy in a multi-sector economy. Specifically, this paper investigates whether it is optimal lFor extensive evidence and explanation, see Stock and Watson (2002, 2003). 2In addition, other explanations might include changes in the structure of economy (McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000), Kahn, McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2002)) and reduction in the variance of exogenous structural shocks (Stock and W'atson (2002, 2003)). 64 for the central bank to use discretionary monetary policies which take account of sectoral impacts in response to structural shocks. Furthermore, this paper also tests the hypothesis that if the central bank had used these discretionary policies, monetary policy could have been more efficient in the sense that monetary policy would have reduced the volatility of output and the inflation rate. To address this issue, we estimate a New— Keynesian type structural model with two sectors: durable goods and nondurable goods. The reason that we choose these two sectors is that these sectors show dramatic differences in response to a change in the nominal interest rate, which is the central bank’s monetary policy instrument. After a rational expectation model is solved, the reduced form structural model is estimated by F1111 Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) estimation method, which is a popular estimation strategy in the literature. One important thing to note is that we must assume the central bank’s specific objective is to minimize the deviation of sectoral or aggregated output and inflation from their targets since we have an interest in the optimal monetary policy. In this paper our interests are limited to the discretionary monetary policy case. To evaluate the optimality of the monetary policy, the traditional approach is to construct an output-inflation variability efficiency frontier. (Cecchetti et al 2004, Fuhrer 1997, Rudebusch 2002, and Taylor 1979). Following the line of research, we obtain the optimal monetary policy trade—off locus by changing policy weight param- eters and by using the estimated model. When we define the discretionary optimal monetary policy as the locus that achieves the lowest possible trade—off between variabilities of inflation and output gap, we can study which discretionary monetary policy regime is optimal, i.e., targeting disaggregated variables, or targeting aggre- gate variables. This comparison also can help us to evaluate whether past monetary policy was optimal. The remainder of the paper is as follows. In section 3.2, we present the complete structural model to be estimated. Section 3.3 describes the data and preliminary estimation results. These results will be used as the starting values later when we estimate the complete model with optimal monetary policy rules. In section 3.4, after 65 we choose the central bank’s objective function, we describe the procedure to obtain the efficiency frontier for monetary policy. Section 3.5 presents and discusses the main results. 3.2 The Structural Model In this section, we present the structural model we estimate. The complete model consists of the intertemporal IS equations, New-Keynesian Phillips curves, and the central bank’s reaction function.3 The below two equations, (3.1) and (3.2), represent the aggregate spending relationship, corresponding to a traditional IS equation. imt = alEti’nJ-l-l + QQP‘nJ—l + 013AEt4I3d,t + O4A(Rt - 7rn,t+1) + umt, (3.1) 536,1 = asEtid¢+decidi—1+07EtAEtin,t+1”rflsEtA13r,t+1+09A(Rt—7Td,t+1Wat) (3.2) where $j,t is the output gap for sector j, defined as output relative to the equilibrium level of output under flexible prices (E 177m — 1772,), A denotes the first-difference, for example, Art = :rt — :rt_1, Rt is the nominal interest rate which the central bank’s policy instrument, 7r“ is the inflation rate for sector j, PM is log relative price level defined as ln(Pd’t/Pn’t) where PJ-J is price level for sector j. Finally, 11” represents the demand shock for sector j. Equation (3.1) represents aggregate demand in the nondurable sector depending on its own expected future and lagged output, the first difference of the ex ante real interest rate and durable goods’ output, and a demand shock. Equation (3.2) is the demand of the durable goods sector. The aggregate demand for durable goods depends on the same arguments except for the first difference of expected relative price and expected nondurable goods’ output. In contrast to traditional models based on individuals’ optimization problem, the aggregate demand of each good is partly determined by the first difference of the ex 3For explicit derivations. refer to the previous chapter. 66 ante real interest rate rather than the level of ex ante real interest rate. The reason is as follows. The representative household obtains utility from the service flow of the durable stock, not the purchase of durable goods. Since the new purchase of durable goods is determined by the difference between current and previous period’s durable stock and the demand for nondurable goods depends on the demand for durable goods, the aggregate demand for both goods are determined by the first difference of arguments which include the ex ante real interest rate. Note that the above specifications extend the theoretical model in two dimensions. First, we allow for degree of backward-looking behavior (02in,t—1 and 0653d,t—1) in order to explain the slow adjustment of output observed in the real world (Fuhrer and Rudebusch (2004)) and to avoid inconsistent estimation caused by serially correlated sectoral demand shocks and lagged dependent variables. Second, we add the forward looking variable, Etid,t+1) to the equation (3.2) to take account of forward looking behavior in the durable goods sector. The following two equations represent sectoral New-Keynesian Phillips curves 7rn,t = 51in,t+)3271n,t—1+53id¢+fi4EtPnt+1+135Pr,t+1+fieEt7rn,t+1+€n,t (3-3) 716,: = fi7id,t+(3877d,t—1+59in,t+fi10EtPr,t+l+511Pr,t+512Et7Id,t+l+ed,t1 (3-4) where the exogenous shock 63¢ for jzn, d is a cost shock. The above two equations describe dynamics of sectoral inflations in both sectors. While sectoral inflations depend on their own current output gaps and future inflations like traditional New-Keynesian Phillips curves, they also are determined by current and future expected relative price gaps and future expected nondurable goods’ output gaps as well. These equations are different from the conventional N ew-Keynesian Phillips curve in two ways. First, when price stickiness is not the same across sectors, relative price fluctuations become another transmission mechanism, which does not exist in the one good aggregate model. In the face of an unexpected monetary shock and changes of 67 relative prices, households and firms will adjust their behavior. In fact, the pressure of relative prices reduces the inflationary effect in that sector because of substitution between the two goods. Second, durability might generate non negligible endogenous dynamics for sectoral inflations. Since durability introduces time non-separability in the utility function into the model, we can see substantial persistence of variables in the model. 3.3 Data and Preliminary Estimation This section describes data used in the estimation, preliminary estimation method- ology and main results. We use quarterly data for the period from 1960Q1 to 2004Q4. Data has been demeaned prior to estimation in order to eliminate constant terms in . the structural equation. All data series are obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the FRED database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The output gap (it) is the percent deviation of sectoral real GDP (measured in chained 2000 dollars) from sectoral potential GDP, i.e. ij,t E 100(ln(GDPj,t) — potential GDPj,t).4 The inflation rate (at) is the annualized quarterly change in the GDP chain-weighted price index, i.e. 7rt E 400(ln(Pt) —ln(Pt_1)). 5 The interest rate (Rt) is the average of monthly rate on a Federal Funds Rate. As a preliminary step, we estimate the structural model by limited information methods. In particular we estimate Intertempotal IS equation (eq.(3.1) and (3.2)) and New-Keynesin Phillips curve (eq. (3.3) and (3.4)) separately by two stage least squares (2SLS).6 We also estimate the system by three stage least squares(3SLS) to exploit efficiency gain by using the contemporaneous covariance among structural 4Since sectoral real GDP data is not available, it is calculated from industry production data in NIPA. After each industry is divided into durable and nondurable goods sector, then the ratio is calculated. This ratio is used to obtain sectoral real GDP data from aggregated real GDP. For the potential GDP, quadratic trend is used, that is, Co + clTrendt + CgTrendtz. But because of possible measurement error, HP filter also is used. 5Since sectoral inflation data also is not available, sectoral price index from durable and non- durable consumption goods are used as proxy for calculation of sectoral inflations. 6For 2SLS estimation, instrument set includes four lags of sectoral output gaps, inflations and relative price index. 68 errors.7 This estimation methodology can help us to obtain initial values that can be used for estimation of the complete structural model by the full information method and to verify the overall specification of the structural model. Table 3.1 shows the estimated results of the Intertemporal IS equation over the durable and nondurable goods sectors. One remarkable result is that parameter esti- mates and standard errors are stable over estimation methods. Parameter estimates in which we have an interest are the forward-looking terms (071 and 075), which rep- resent the effect of expected sectoral future output, and ea: ante real interest rate sensitivity (04 and 09). Table 3.1: Estimation Results of the Intertemporal IS Equation in,t=011Et53n,t+1 + agin,t_1 + a3(id,t — id,t—1)A+ a4A(Rt — 7rn,t+1) + amt, id,t=05Etid,t+1+06id,t—1+07EtAin¢+1+08EtAPr,t+1+093(Rt— "(Lt+1)+ud,t ZSLS 3SLS Coefficient I P-Value Coefficient L P-Value 6.1 0.589 (0.086) 0.000 0.589 (0.104) 0.000 (12 0.422 (0.081) 0.000 0.422 (0.100) 0.000 03 0.006 (0.027) 0.807 0.006 (0.035) 0.858 04 -0.028 (0.072) 0.698 -0.028 (0.073) 0.703 (15 0.590 (0.074) 0.000 0.590 (0.078) 0.000 06 0.434 (0.063) 0.000 0.434 (0.070) 0.000 07 -0555 (0.751) 0.383 0.543 (0.721) 0.373 08 0.197 (0.381) 0.604 0.196 (0.495) 0.692 69 -0030 (0.205) 0.885 0032 (0.187) 0.865 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. The coefficient estimates of the forward-looking term across the two sectors are 0.589, which all are significantly different from zero. On the other hand, the estimated degree of backward looking behavior in aggregated sectoral demand is 0.422, which are all significant and implies persistence in sectoral outputs. This result indicates that forward looking behavior seems as important as backward looking behavior. The relative importance of forward looking behavior is a controversial issue in empirical macroeconomic literature. By using a one good econometric model and full informa- tion maximum likelihood estimation (FIML), Fuhrer and Rudebusch (2004) estimate 7If all equations are correctly specified, system procedure such as 3SLS is more efficient. than a single-equation procedure such as 2SLS. But single-equation methods are more robust. 69 the degree of forward looking to be between 0 and 0.4. while they estimate the degree of backward looking to be between 0.53 and 0.99. Then they conclude that rational expectations of future output are not important for the determination of current out- put. In addition, Lindé (2002) and Rudebusch (2002) obtain 0.43 and 0.30 for the degree of forward looking behavior, while Siiderstriim et al (2005) estimate it to be 0.56 which is similar to our estimates. Regarding parameters (074 and 019) that govern real interest sensitivity in both sectors, the real interest rate coefficient estimates are of the correct sign, but are not significantly different from zero over both estimations. In addition, absolute value of the durable goods sector’s real interest sensitivity is greater than that of the nondurable goods sector’s. This implies that the durable goods sector is a little more sensitive to ex ante real interest than the nondurable goods sector. This finding is also consistent with Mankiw (1985), Gali (1987). Table 3.2 shows the estimation results of sectoral New-Keynesian Phillips curves over durable and nondurable goods sectors. We also report the p-values for the J- statistic, which all are not significant. Thus the instruments we have chosen appear valid. The slope coefficients (61 and 67) have the correct signs over both sectors and estimation methods. But coefficients of durable goods sectors are not significant. These estimated coefficients appear to be consistent with earlier research. Those vary from 0.015 to 0.13 (Fuhrer (1997), Gali and Gerther (1999), Lindé(2002), and Rude— busch (2002)). In terms of the effect of the output gap on current sectoral inflation, note that the output gap of the nondurable goods sector causes greater impact on current sectoral inflation than that of the durable goods sector. The estimates of the coefficients (67 and 614) on expected inflation are between 0.55 and 0.59. All estimates are significant and greater than the estimates of past sectoral inflations, i.e 62 and ,88. This evidence indicates that expected future inflation is slightly more important than past inflation for the determination of inflation dynamics. Research has shown conflicting evidence about relative importance of expected future and past inflation. Gali and Gertler (1999) and Sbordone (2002) argue that forward looking behavior, i.e expected future inflation, is quantitatively important while backward 70 Table 3.2: Estimation Results of the Phillips Curve "mt = 6113712 + (32717151 + 63116,: + fi4Etlfr,t+1 + 651351 + fl6Et7In,t+1 + 871,5 716,5 5753d,t + fi8”d,t—1 + 5913712 + 510EtPr,t+1 + 511331 + 512Et77d,t+1 + 66,1 2SLS 3SLS Coefficient I p-value Coefficient L p-value (31 0.084 (0.042) 0.047 0.066 (0.035) 0.055 62 0.389 (0.119) 0.001 0.406 (0.087) 0.000 63 -0.027 (0.013) 0.039 -0.023 (0.010) 0.025 64 0.753 (0.245) 0.002 0.652 (0.211) 0.002 55 -0.694 (0.242) 0.004 -0.606 (0.209) 0.004 66 0.553 (0.115) 0.000 0.555 (0.085) 0.000 137 0.011 (0.012) 0.347 0.015 (0.011) 0.178 68 0.460 (0.051) 0.000 0.507 (0.037) 0.000 139 -0.070 (0.053) 0.189 -0.075 (0.054) 0.165 310 -0.947 (0.276) 0.001 -0.855 (0.260) 0.001 611 0.902 (0.263) 0.001 0.805 (0.251) 0.001 312 0.594 (0.065) 0.000 0.545(0.045) 0.000 J-test(p-value) Eq.(3): 0.534, Eq.(4): 0.396 0.579 Note: Standard errors in parentheses. looking behavior, i.e., past inflation is of limited quantitative importance. On the other hand, Fuhrer (1997), Robert (2001), and Rudebusch (2002) argue that the New-Keynesian model with only forward looking behavior does not fit the US. data and requires additional lags of inflation not implied under rational expectations. Our results support the evidence that Gali and Gertler (1999) and Sbordone (2002) sug- gested. Finally, we close the structural model by estimating the reaction function of the central bank. In what follows, we assume that the central bank uses the Federal Funds Rate (Rt) as its instrument. The specific functional form is given by Rt = PRt—l + (1 - (9)017 + uyfvt) + 5t (3-5) where R is the Federal Funds Rate (the instrument of monetary policy), [17; is the aggregate inflation rate and 3:15 is the aggregate output gap. This is the modified Taylor rule with an additional lagged interest rate Rt.8 This lagged term can help 8For detailed derivation of the functional form, see Gah’ and Gertler (1999). Since we use demeand data, This equation does not constant term. 71 to explain the large persistence in the nominal interest rate (see e.g., Clarida et al. (2000), Woodford (1999)). We will use this form of reaction function as the baseline monetary policy rule later. Table 3.3: Estimation Results of the Reaction Function Rt = pRt—l + (1 - Mum + Myrrt) + 8t p p-value 11W p—value 11y p-value R2 Whole sample 0.907 0.000 1.257 0.034 0.836 0.070 0.921 (0.039) (0.595) (0.462) Pre—1979:Q3 0.886 0.000 0.184 0.720 1.013 0.011 0.892 (0.038) (0.514) (0.397) Post-1979Q3 0.859 0.000 2.053 0.001 0.483 0.143 0.934 (0.054) (0.592) (0.330) Note: Standard errors in parentheses. RTdenotes the adjusted R2. Whole sample period is 1960Q1-2004Q4. Table 3.3 shows the estimation results of the modified Taylor rule by ordinary least squares (OLS). Since the estimation results are sensitive to the choice of sample period (e.g., Soderstrom et al. (2005) and US. monetary policy has been changed dramatically in the late 1970s (Gali et al. (2000)), we also report the estimation results with pre and post 1979Q3 sample periods. Over three sample periods, the lagged interest rate explains the dynamics of the interest rate well, which means that the short-term interest rate has substantial per- sistence. The other thing to note is that the response coefficient (#77) to inflation is relatively high and significant in the post 1979Q3 period. This result supports the finding of Clarida, et al.(2000) who suggests that for the post 1979 rule the estimate is significantly above unity. We will use the above rule as the baseline rule when we evaluate other monetary policy rules. 3.4 Discretionary Policy and Loss Function Given the empirical model described above, we examine the performance of three specific discretionary policies in terms of the central bank’s objective function. Since we consider two different sectors, it is assumed that the central bank’s objective func- tion has sectoral output gaps and inflations as arguments. This approach is consistent 72 with that of Blinder and Mankiw (1984), Waller (1992), Duca and VanHoose (1990), even though they did not consider inflation as an argument.9 As a baseline case, the central bank’s objective function is assumed to be of the form: . 1 0° - Mm 50—813: 20%] . (36) 2'20 2 2 2 2 Lt = ”n,t+i+7rd,t+i+“”$n,t+i+“dxd,t+i’ (37) where the parameter pj is the relative weight on output deviations in sector j, 6 is the discount factor. This objective function assumes that target inflations and output gaps in both sectors are zero. Therefore, expected loss equals the weighted sum of unconditional variances, E(Lt) = VaT(7rn,t) + VaT(7Td,t) + unVaT($n,t) + Hal/070111) (3-8) In the literature concerning stabilization of the economy, many discussions have been built on one good models. In this case, it is assumed that the central bank minimizes the following loss function 1 °° . Min 5(1—fi)Et 2521181 . (3.9) i=0 Lt == 73+.+Aaw?+5 (3.10) where /\a is the relative weight on the aggregate output gap. Finally, we consider the policy to only target the durable goods sector (DGT). Then the policy objective is given by DGT __ 2 2 where )‘dg is the weight on output gap of the durable goods sector. 9We will examine the policy implication in next section, as the central bank’s objective function depends on aggregated variables. 73 3.5 Estimation and Optimal Policy Frontier In this section, we present our empirical results and interpretations. Since the model includes rational expectation terms, we should solve the model for the reduced form first before we implement estimation. In this paper, we solve the problem by following Séderlind’s approach (1999) with the assumption that the central bank implements discretionary monetary policy. Then after we specify the conditional log- likelihood function, we can obtain the Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) estimates. 3.5.1 Parameter Estimates F IML estimates are shown in Table 3.4 . Standard errors are obtained as the inverse of the Hessian Matrix. Each column represents estimation results under dif- ferent monetary policy regimes. For example, the first column (Case (1)) is the result in which the central bank implements discretionary monetary policy to target the de- viation of sectoral inflations (77mg and 7rd,t) and output gaps ($7M and de)’ While the second column (Case (2)) reports the result under the assumption that the cen- tral bank targets the deviation of aggregate inflation and output gap (at and act), the last column (Case (3)) represents the result when the central bank targets only the durable goods sector’s inflation (7rd,t) and output gap (10¢)- In terms of coefficients of intertemporal IS equation (a ’8) across different mone- tary policy regimes, estimates of the forward-looking term across the two sectors ((11 and a5) vary from 0.32 to 0.589, which all are significantly different from zero while the estimates of backward looking behavior vary from 0.1 to 0.45. Across monetary policy regimes, estimates of the nondurable goods sector’s IS equation implies that forward looking behavior is more important than backward looking behavior while the durable goods sector shows mixed results. The results also show that coefficients associated with the real interest rate sen- sitivity (a4 and 09) are estimated poorly. Size and sign of some coefficients are not consistent with theoretical prediction as well. Therefore, a comparison of Table 74 (1) Lt=7rn,t+7rd,t+“nxn.t+#dxd,t (3) Lt:7rd,t+)‘d9xd,t 071 0.5890 (1.0000) 0.5895 (0.0000) 0.5890 (1.0000) 02 0.1831 (0.0005) 0.4398 (0.0358) 0.4338 (0.0006) (13 -0.1634 (0.0019) 0.0253 (0.0203) 0.0229 (0.0005) (14 -0.9217 (0.0006) -0.I262 (0.0044) 0.0130 (0.0000) 05 0.3218 (0.0001) 0.5429 (0.0055) 0.4598 (0.0002) 06 0.6128 (0.0000) 0.4602 (0.0167) 0.4502 (0.0004) 07 -0.2287 (0.0002) -0.6305 (0.0308) ~0.6425 (0.0003) 0'8 -0.3736 (0.0023) 0.1699 (0.0169) 0.2509 (0.0006) 09 0.4326 (0.0004) 0.0362 (0.0071) -0.0591 (0.0005) (31 0.1431 (0.0002) 0.0232 (0.0280) 0.0427 (0.0000) 732 0.5057 (0.0001) 0.4319 (0.0200) 0.4578 (0.0000) (33 —0.0334 (0.0001) -0.0244 (0.0073) -0.0275 (0.0000) [34 1.0195 (0.0008) 0.6314 (0.0395) 0.5987 (0.0002) [35 -0.8689 (0.0007) -0.6751 (0.0105) —0.5978 (0.0002) {36 0.4511 (0.0001) 0.5068 (0.0434) 0.5630 (0.0000) (’37 0.0734 (0.0001) 0.0246 (0.0074) 0.0197(0.0001) (’38 0.6208 (0.0001) 0.5130 (0.0040) 0.4670 (0.0001) [39 -0.3175 (0.0001) -0.0398 (0.0310) -0.0482 (0.0001) [310 -1.4023 (0.0007) -0.8075 (0.0106) -0.7777 (0.0000) 6'11 1.2163 (0.0003) 0.8300 (0.0428) 0.8175 (0.0000) 612 0.1596 (0.0001) 0.5080 (0.0324) 0.5224 (0.0002) Note: Standard errors in parentheses. 3.4 with Table 3.1 shows that FIML estimation is not always better than the single equation estimation approach in contrast to Lindé(2002). Finally, we can see that estimates from the single equation approach (Table 3.1) are closer to those from FIML under the assumption that the central bank targets the deviation of aggregate inflation and output gap (Case (2)). In other-words, this result indicates that monetary policy targeting aggregate inflation and the output gap explains historical data better than any other monetary policy regimes. It seems to be consistent with the traditional view and assumption by Barro and Gordon (1982) and Svensson (1997, 1999) about monetary policy objective. In general, estimates of New-Keynesian Phillips curve (13’s) are stable across mon- etary policy regimes in contrast to estimates of intertemporal IS equation. Size and sign of estimated parameters are reasonable and consistent with the single equation estimation (Table 3.2). Estimates of the forward—looking term across the two sectors 75 ((36 and 612) vary from 0.15 to 0.56, which are all significantly different from zero while the estimates of backward looking behavior (62 and 68) vary from 0.43 to 0.62. In Case (1), backward looking behavior is more important than forward looking be- havior in both sectors while Case (3) indicates that forward looking behavior is more important and Case (2) shows mixed result across sectors. These results indicate that the monetary policy regimes could be a factor in determining the relative importance between forward and backward looking behavior. 3.5.2 Optimal Policy Frontier In this subsection, we compute the “optimal policy frontier”: the set of efficient combinations of inflation variance and output variance attainable by policymakers. But note that the frontier says nothing about what combinations are desirable. Then we evaluate monetary policy regimes using the policy frontier. Given the structure of economy and the monetary policy regime, each optimal monetary policy frontier is calculated and compared. In this paper, the more efficient monetary policy is defined as the combinations of standard deviation close to the origin of policy frontier. The values of standard deviations depends on the shocks experienced by the economy as well. In this paper, since we assume that all structural shocks are same over monetary policy regimes, we can exclude the possibility of change of policy frontier curve caused by shocks (See, for example Cecchetti, Flores-Lagunes and Kraus (2004), and Stock and Watson (2003)). In other words, with the same amount of structural shock, the monetary policy which shifts the policy frontier close to origin is more efficient. Each point on a frontier corresponds to a different relative weight on aggregate (or disaggregate) inflation and output gap variability. Specifically, given the model specification and parameter estimates, the monetary policy regime that targets disag- gregate variables solves the optimization problem represented by equation (6) to (8). The upper panel of Figure 3.1 represents the policy frontier over a grid for #71 and #d from 0.0 to 1 in increments of 0.05, when the central bank implements the monetary 76 S. D. of Inflation S. D. of Inflation 0.296 0.294 0.292 0.290 0.288 0.286 0.284 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 I 1 l r I l 0.48 0.50 0.52 0.54 0.56 0.58 S. D. of Output Gap d -( I l I i 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.2 S. D. of Output Gap Figure 3.1: Optimal Policy Frontier 77 policy to seek to minimize the deviation of disaggregate inflations and output gaps from their targets. For low relative weight on disaggregate output gaps, the cost to reduce inflation in terms of standard deviation of aggregate output gap is very high. One thing to note is that for some high relative policy weights, the policy frontier shows positive relationship between standard deviations of aggregate inflation and output gap. This implies that in this interval, the central bank does not face a policy trad-off. The bottom panel of Figure 3.1 represents the policy frontier over a grid for /\a from 0.0 to 1 in increments of 0.05, when the central bank implements the monetary policy to seek to minimize the deviation of aggregate inflations and output gap from their targets (eq.(3.9) and (3.10). This policy frontier is consistent with conventional wisdom (Taylor (1979), Fuhrer (1997) and Rudebusch (2002)) since we assumed that the central bank minimizes the loss function depending on aggregate inflation and output gap. According to the graph, we can see that the policy long run trade—off relationship exists in the two goods model. The main result of this experiment comes from the comparison of the above two graphs. Considering the scale of the two graphs, the policy frontier in which the central bank targets disaggregate variables (upper left panel) is closer to the origin than policy frontier in which the central bank targets aggregate variables (upper right panel). This implies that the past monetary policy could have been more effective if the central bank had been concerned about sectoral stabilization. A crucial assump— tion for this result is that the true loss function depends on sectoral inflations and output gaps. Since we assumed that aggregate inflation and output gap are defined as the linear combination of disaggregate inflations and output gaps, the stabilization of disaggregate variables results in the low variability of disaggregate variables and thus aggregate variables. On the other hand, the monetary policy to target aggregate variables does not care about fluctuations of disaggregate inflations and output gaps. Thus the policy results in higher volatility of aggregate variables even if the policy objective of central bank is targeting aggregate variables. Under the assumption that the central bank implements the monetary policy to 78 target only one sector (in our case, the durable goods sector, eq.(3.11)), Figure 3.2 represents the policy frontier of durable goods sector’s inflation and output gap. In contrast to previous two cases, the locus represents the combinations of durable goods sector’s inflation and output gap. In this policy regime, the trade-off relationship between aggregate inflation and output gap dose not exist. Thus it is possible to obtain the lowest variability of inflation and output gap. In our experiment, the relative weight on durable sector’s output gap ( Adg) is 1. 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 L 0.6 S. D. of Inflation 0.4 0.2 ,, I I I 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1 .2 S. D. of Output Gap Figure 3.2: Optimal Policy Frontier(DGT) 3.5.3 Sensitivity Analysis This section implements the robustness analysis of the computed optimal policy frontier with respect to the exact specification. Figure 3.3 represents the changed policy frontier (dashed line) with respect to the change of impact of relative price gap on the aggregate demand (Intertemporal IS equation).10 Specifically, the new policy frontier is calculated under the assumption that the impact of relative price gap(c18) is zero. 10The original policy frontier is represented by the solid line. 79 S. D. of Inflation S. D. of Inflation 0.300 0.295 0.290 0.285 0.280 0.275 0.270 0.265 0.260 0.255 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 Y I ‘U 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 S. D. of Output Gap V I 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 S. D. of Output Gap Figure 3.3: Sensitivity Analysis of Policy Hontier 80 S. D. of Inflation S. D. of Inflation 0. 305 0.300 0.295 0.290 0.285 0.280 0.275 0.270 0.265 0.260 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 h ‘5‘ ..I I I I 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 S. D. of Output Gap "1 'I 'l .l 'I a 0‘. I" "-‘ ' x I‘__ x I.“ 1. a I I I l 1 2 3 4 5 S. D. of Output Gap Figure 3.4: Sensitivity Analysis of Policy Frontier 81 The upper panel is the policy frontier in which the central bank seek to minimize the deviation of disaggregated inflations and output gaps from their targets. Since we ignore the effect of relative price on aggregate demand, combinations of standard deviations of aggregate inflation and output gap shift to the origin. In other words, the policy trade—off that the central bank faces is improved as we expect. The bottom panel is the policy frontier in which the central bank’s objective is to minimize the deviations of aggregate variables from their targets. In this case, the policy frontier is relatively insensitive to the absence of relative price effect. The comparison of two graphs shows that the policy frontier in which the central bank targets disaggre- gated variables achieves the lower combinations of volatility of aggregate inflation and output gap. This results suggests that the monetary policy targeting disaggregated inflations and output gaps has a possibility that the policy trade—off relationship the central bank faces could be improved. The Figure 3.4 represents the new policy frontier (dashed line) in which the structure of the economy has no backward looking term in aggregate demand, that is, £12 and 06 are equal to zero. The upper panel represents the policy frontier in which the central bank targets disaggregate inflations and output gaps while the right panel is the case that the central bank targets aggregate inflation and output gap. In both cases, the policy frontier shifts to the right side. But the comparison of the two graphs shows that even with no ”backward-lookingness”, discretionary monetary policy targeting disaggregate variables can achieve lower combinations of volatilities of aggregate inflation and output gap than the discretionary policy targeting aggregated inflation and output gap. 3.6 Conclusion In this paper, we estimate a two sector New-Keynesian structural model and evaluate alternative monetary policy regimes. The estimated two sector model and alternative policy regimes are used to calculate the optimal monetary policy frontier. W’e find that changes in monetary policy responses to aggregate or disaggregate 82 inflations and output gaps can imply substantial differences in long—run inflation and output variances. More interestingly, the location of the optimal monetary policy frontier implies that the past monetary policy could have been more effective if the central bank had been concerned about sectoral stabilization. But we have to note one thing. The optimal policy frontier is just attainable combinations of inflation and output gap variances. Thus the monetary policy to care about sectoral stabilization can achieve the location close to the origin does not mean that it is more effective than the policy to care about aggregated variables. The result of this paper suggests simply that the former provides the central bank with the available opportunity set of combinations of lower volatilities of inflation and the output gap. Considering the uncertainty about the structure of economy and data used, the result of this paper shows that sectoral stabilization is as important as traditional stabilization policy if people care about their own sector or industry. 83 Appendix A Appendix F irm’s profit maximization problem is oo "‘6 _6 . Pdt(Z) Wt kfpdtle Max E, 50)"), k P (z) ’ m k— + ’ Ydt k (A.1) F.O.C Pt+k 9 - 1 Pt+k Pd,t+k 8943+}. (A.2) —0 0" P (2') k d,t Et 2 (073) At,t+k( ) Yd,t+k Pd,t(2) 9 Wt+k Pt+k 1 ]=0 [:20 Pt+k By using household’s first condition, —0 I ¢—1 k d,t pd,t 3,t+k t+k E —— Y . A - - =0. A.3 t E (afl) ( + ) d,t+I. t,t+l. Pd,t+k 6—1 8941+]: ( ) Log-linearization: LHS of bracket term of above equation, If we know the fact that Pn t(Z) P71 t(Z) P71 t j t = 1’n,t 75;— . , (57(1— (3(1— 6) - 730—5) A = — — Y -+ ° A4 t,t+k xd,t+k 1 __ 6(1— (5)2 dat‘f’t (1_/3(1_5)2) ( ) . . 1—6 . . (“OI/11.,t+k+1+PR,t+k+1] + (1—13(1—-6)2) [-UYnJ+k—1+PR.t+k—1] _)(1-.3(1-5)) (1—6) - (1—(1—5)L)132,t+ 'U1’1,t—1a (1—/3(1_6)2) (1530—6)?) 84 Z where pdt(z=log(?§1%(t—)). RHS of bracketed term of above equation: First, by using production and demand function, 8—1 —0(-1))ZM,1+1 +w3.t+k i=1 7(1—50—6» _ ’- _ 1-5 I.) where L represents the one period lag operator. Let denote 2:” represents the natural rate of variable X. The equation (A6) can be written as 00 1—0161)”13(1 5) ‘ ‘n = (1+9? )E‘tZéafi) WW 1_ --fl(1 (5)2 +¢‘1)(Yd,t+k-Yd,t+k) [:2 + Y” )— (P — P" ) (1_ :(1— 6M2 (Yn,t+k— 1 n,t+k—l r,t+k—-1 r,t+k—l n A ”n (1— 313(1—fl55):2){( Ynt+k+l_ Yn,t+k+1)_(Pr,t+k+1‘Pr,t+k+1)} 00 +(1—aB)Et Z (amk 2: 7rd,”, (A.7) k: '— 85 By some algebra and calculation, following relationship is satisfied: 00 k 00 1 23W 2er = —<1 .. am 80/387151 (A8) and Pd’t(z) = 7rd,t (A.9) 1 — 0 Substituting above equation into equation (A.7), we obtain New-Keynesian Phillips curve of the durable sector in the text. 86 Bibliography [1] Aoki, K., 2001. Optimal monetary responses to relative-price changes, Journal of Monetary Economics 48 55-80. [2] Backus, D., and A. Driffill., 1986. The Consistency of Optimal Policy in Stochastic Rational Expectations Models, Discussion Paper no.124, CEPR, London. [3] Ball, L., 1999. Efficient Rules for Monetary Policy, International Finance, 2(1) 63-83. [4] Barro, R.J. and D. B. Gordon, 2001. A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural-Rate Model, Journal of Political Economy, 91(4) 589-610. [5] Barsky, R., C. L. House, and M. Kimball, 2003. Do flexible durable goods prices undermine sticky price model? N BER Working Paper 9832. [6] Baxter, M., 1996. Are Consumer Durables Important For Business Cycles?, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol 78 no.1 147-155. [7] Benigno, P., 2004. Optimal monetary policy in a currency area, Journal of Inter- national Economics, vol. 63(2) 293-320. [8] Bernanke, BS. and A. S. Blinder, 1992. The Federal Fund Rate and the Channels of Monetary Policy, American Economic Review, 82(4):901-92l. [9] Bils, M., P. J. Klenow, and O. Kryvtsov, 2003. Sticky Prices and Monetary Policy Shocks, Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Vol 27, No 1, 2-9. [10] Blinder, AS. and N. G. Mankiw, 1984. Aggregation and Stabilization Policy In A Multi-Contract Economy, Journal of Monetary Economics, 13 67—86. [11] Boivin, Jean and Marc P. Giannoni, 2003, Has Monetary Policy Become More Effective?, N BER Working Papers 9459. [12] Bordo, M., 1980. The Effects of Monetary Change on Relative Commodity Prices and the Role of Long-Term Contracts, Journal of Political Economy, 88(6) 1088- 1109. [13] Cecchetti, Stephen G., Alfonso Flores-Lagunes and Stefan Krause, 2004, Has Monetary Policy Become More Efficient? A Cross Country Analysis, N BER Work- ing Papers 10973. 87 [14] Chari, V. V., Kehoe, P. J., and McGrattan E. R., Sticky price Models of the Business Cycle: Can the Contract Multipliers Solve the Persistent Problems? NBER Working Paper 5809, 1996. [15] Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gal and Mark Gertler, 2000, Monetary Policy Rules And Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence And Some Theory, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 115(1), 147-180. [16] Christiano, L J ., Eichenbaum, Martin., Evans, C L., 2001, Nominal rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy, Working Paper 0107, FRB of Cleveland. May, [17] Currie, D. and P. Levine, 1995. Rules, Reputation and Macroeconomic Policy Coordination, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [18] Domowitz, I., R. G. Hubbard, and B. C. Petersen, 1988. Market Structure and Cyclical Fluctuations in US. Manufacturing, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol 70 No 1. 55-66. [19] Dotsey, M., and R. King, 2001, Pricing, Production and Persistence, NBER Working paper, w8407. [20] Duca, J.V. and D. D. VanHoose, 1990. Optimal Monetary Policy in a Multisec- tor Economy with an Economywide Money Market, Journal of Economics and Business, 42:253-263. [21] Erceg, J ., and A. T. Levin, 2002. Optimal Montary Policy with Durable and Non-Durable Goods, Discussion Paper, Federal Reserve Board. [22] Fuhrer, Jeffrey C., 1997, Inflation/Output Variance Trade-Offs and Optimal Monetary Policy, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 29, No.2 214-234. [23] Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. and Glenn D. Rudebusch, 2004, Estimating the Euler equation for Output, Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 1133-1153. [24] Gali, Jordi, 1993, Variability of Durable and Nondurable Consumption: Evidence for Six O.E.C.D. Countries, The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 75(3), 418-28. [25] Gali, Jordi and Gertler, Mark, 1999, Inflation dynamics: A structural economet- ric analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol.44(2), 195-222. [26] Jensen, H., 2002. Targeting Nominal Income or Inflation?, American Economic Review, 92(4):928-956. [27] Kahn, James, Margaret M. McConnell and Gabriel Perez-Quiros, 2002, On the Causes of the Increased Stability of the US. Economy, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic Policy Review 8, 183-202. [28] Kiley, M. T ., 1997, Staggered Price Setting, Partial Adjustment, Real Rigidities, and Sunspots, Unpublished Paper, Federal Reaserve Board. 88 [29] King, Robert, G., and Sergio T. Rebelo., 1999. Resuscitating Real Business Cycle, Handbook of Macroeconomics, Ch 14, 927-007. [30] Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott, 1977. Rule rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plan, Journal of Political Economy, 85 473-491. [31] Leeper, EM. and CA. Sims, and T. Zha, 1996, What Does Monetary Policy Do?, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1-63. [32] Lindé, Jesper, 2005, Estimating New-Keynesian Phillips curves: A full informa- tion maximum likelihood approach, Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1135- 1149. [33] Mankiw, N. G., 1985. Consumer Durables and Real Interest Rate, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(3), 353-362. [34] Mann, M., 1969. How Does Monetary Policy Affect the Economy, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Aug 538-548. [35] McConnell, Margaret M. and Gabriel Perez Quiros, 2000, Output fluctuations in the United States: what has changed since the early 1980s? American Economic Review, Vol. 90, N05, 1464-1476. [36] Ohanian, L., A. Stockman, and L. Kilian, 1995. The effects of real and money shocks in a business cycle model with some sticky prices, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 27(4) 34-1209. [37] Roberts, John M. ”How Well Does the New Keynesian Sticky-Price Model Fit the Data?” Contributions to Macroeconomics, vol. 5, pp. 1-37. [38] Rogoff, K., 1985. The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Internediate Mon- etary Target, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 1169-1189. [39] Rotemberg, J. J. and M. Woodford, 1998. An Opimization-Based Economet- ric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy, NBER Technical Working Paper, No 233. [40] Rudebusch, Glenn D., 2002, Assessing Nominal Income Rules For Monetary Policy with Model and Data Uncertainty, The Economic Journal, 112 (April), 402-432. [41] Sbordone, Argia M., 2002, Prices. and unit labor costs: a new test of price stickiness, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 49(2), 265-292. [42] S6derlind, P., 1999. Solution and eatimation of RE macromodels with optimal policy, European Economic Review, 43:813—823. [43] S6derstrm, U1f., Paul Séderlind and Anders Vredin, 2005, New-Keynesian Mod- els and Monetary Policy: A Re-examination of the Stylized Facts, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, vol. 107(3), 521-546. [44] Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson, 2002, Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why?, NBER Working Papers 9127. 89 [45] Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson, 2003, Has the business cycle changed?, Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pages 9-56. [46] Svensson, L. E. O., 1997. Inflation Forecast Targetingzlmplementing and Moni- toring Inflation Target, European Economic Review, 41: 1111-1146. [47] Svensson, L. E. O., 1999. Inflation Targeting as a Monetary Policy Rule, Journal of Monetary Economics, 43: 607-654. [48] Taylor, J. B., 1979. Estimation and Control of a Macroeconomic Model with Rational Expectations, Econometrica, Vol. 47, No 5, 1267-1286. [49] Taylor, J. B., 1993. Discretion versus Policy Rules Practice, Carnegie-Rochester Conference series Public Policy, 39, pp. 195-214. [50] Waller, C. J., 1992. The Choice of a Conservative Central Banker in a Multisector Economy, American Economic Review, 82(4):1006-1012. [51] Walsh, C. E., 2003a, Monetary Theory and Policy, Massachusetts: MIT Press. [52] Walsh, C.E., 2003b, Speed limit policies: The Output Gap and Optimal Mone- tary Policy, American Economic Review, 93(1), 265—278. [53] Weder, M., 1998. Fickle Consumers, Durable Goods, and Business Cycle, Journal of Economic Theory, 81, 37-57. [54] Woodford, M., 1999. Optimal Monetary Policy Inertia, NBER Working Paper N0. 7261, Aug. [55] Woodford, M., 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundation of a Theory of Monetary Policy, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. 90