p .- . IHWM. - .r.‘i-.1....:.w.flm.:.. :1. (‘Ivilr’ .: t I! . .1 :1 x?... we“. .I. V v a .x {7 )3) .4 .1 . y .250 \. r 4.. u. 11...... and». .4“. at; .1 u! 43...”... ll VA) 53.2111. $1.31 4.25%. 2 LIBRARY 20 a; Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled OPTIMAL PEST MANAGEMENT IN THE PRESENCE OF NATURAL PEST CONTROL SERVICES presented by Wei Zhang has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Umbra/g in Agrjzatturai Economics Major Professor's Signature ”Pa: ~ Q, 2007’ Date MSU is an affinnative-action, equal-opportunity employer PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/07 p:/ClRC/DateDue.indd-p.1 OPTIMAL PEST MANAGEMENT IN THE PRESENCE OF NATURAL PEST CONTROL SERVICES By Wei Zhang A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 2007 ABSTRACT OPTIMAL PEST MANAGEMENT IN THE PRESENCE OF NATURAL PEST CONTROL SERVICES By Wei Zhang By integrating natural pest control services into managerial decision-making, there are new opportunities for improving agricultural pest management in an economically appealing and socially desirable manner. This research develops dynamic and spatial bioeconomic models to investigate optimal economic management of an insect pest in the presence of natural enemies. Of central economic importance are the opportunity cost of natural enemy mortality due to broad-spectrum insecticides and the opportunity cost of setting aside land as non-crop habitats for the enhancement of natural enemy populations. The models are applied to a recent invasive pest of US. soybean, the soybean aphid, whose management is of both economic and environmental importance to the North Central region of the United States. The thesis is divided into three essays. Essay 1 develops a dynamic bioeconomic model for the insecticide-based management of soybean aphid that explicitly takes into account both the predation effect of natural enemies on pest density and the nontarget mortality effect of aphid insecticides on the level of natural predation supplied. The study develops a natural enemy-adj usted economic threshold that represents the pest population density at which pesticide control becomes optimal in spite of the opportunity cost of injury to natural enemies of the target pest. Essay 2 applies the bioeconomic model developed in Essay 1 for a simulation experiment on the optimal control of soybean aphid. The study examines the difference in optimal control choices and associated economic gains with and without consideration of natural enemies. For instance, the presence of one ladybeetle would justify a change of optimal control choice from spray to no-spray when the pest density is 20 per plant. The results highlight the importance of assessing both pest and natural enemy populations in making insecticide application decisions and accounting for the opportunity cost of insecticide collateral damage to natural enemies. The study also estimates the private economic value to farmers of the natural control services of ladybeetles in suppressing soybean aphid damage. The estimate constitutes a lower bound for the total economic value of this ecosystem service, because it omits such benefits as the avoidance of health and environmental risks from insecticide spraying. Farmers desiring to rely on natural pest control in lieu of insecticide-based control can try to manage the habitat for natural enemies. Essay 3 develops a spatial optimization model to explore economically optimal habitat configurations for the natural enemies of crop pests. The model is applied to soybean aphid management in representative conventional and organic farming systems. Results indicate that non-crop habitat management can potentially be a promising pest management option for organic cropping systems. However, it tends to reduce farm net returns for conventional farms. Both area and shape of non-crop habitats affect economic performance, with the greatest value coming from small, scattered areas of habitat. Copyright by WEI ZHANG 2007 To my parents, my husband, and my sister for their love and support, and to those who still believe in making a difference... ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I feel fortunate to have two wonderful advisors steering me through my doctoral program. I would like to thank my major advisor, Richard Horan, for his guidance and support throughout this process. I am grateful to him for being a great inspiration in so many ways, for introducing me into the wonderful world of bioeconomic modeling with his intelligent and effective teaching, for continuing providing constructive comments and suggestions on my research, even though he was not involved in the dissertation project, and for contributing greatly to my personal and professional development. I would like to thank my dissertation research supervisor, Scott M. Swinton, who has also filled the functions of a major professor since we first worked together. I trust and respect him as a great advisor, mentor, and friend. I deeply appreciate his kindness, encouragement, patience, concern for my well being, and for opening the doors to so many opportunities for me. I am grateful to him for his constant support and outstanding efficiency in responding to my questions and writings, which made the completion of this work possible. Not only have I learned from him on research but also on writing, organizing, critical thinking, and communication, qualities that will benefit me for the rest of my life. I would like to express my appreciation to the members of my committee, Sandra Batie and Douglas Landis, for the valuable contributions they have made to the improvement of this work and for the support they have given me along the way. I thank Sandra Batie for being a great role model for female environmental economists and for her generous help with my professional development. I am grateful to Douglas Landis for vi providing collaboration opportunities and crucial data sources for the research, and for making time teaching me about insect ecology and sharing ideas. I am grateful to our collaborator, Wopke van der Werf, who traveled trans- Atlantic to East Lansing to work with us on the habitat management study. I appreciate his professionalism, his valuable contributions to the development of the research questions and spatial model, and stimulating ideas and comments that have greatly improved the work. I enjoy very much his sincerity, humor, and concern for students’ well being. I also would like to express my gratitude to the support of the Kellogg Biological Station Long-Term Ecological Research program and the dedication of the members of the soybean aphid USDA Risk Assessment and Mitigation Program team. I would especially like to thank Alejandro Costamagna, Mary Gardiner, Chris DiFonzo, Mike Brewer, and Stuart Gage for their kind help and constructive discussions. I greatly appreciate their time and efforts. Special thanks to Felix Bianchi for his help on ecological modeling and Tim Harrigan for taking the time to help me with habitat establishment cost estimation. I would like to express my appreciation to the faculty and staff of the Department of Agricultural Economics for all of their help and support throughout my time here. I would especially like to thank Robert Myers, Eric Crawford, Zhengfei Guan, John Hoehn, Debbie Conway, Cynthia Donovan, and Larry Borton. Many thanks go to fellow graduate students. In particular, I would like to thank Yanyan Liu, Laila Racevskis, Julius Kirimi Sindi, Zhiying Xu, F eng Song, Lili Gao, Honglin Wang, Sarma Aralas, Elan Satriawan, Feng Wu, Fang Xie, Catherine Ragasa, vii Wolfgang Pejuan, Ricardo Labarta-Chavarri, Laura Donnet, Tomokazu Nagai, and Rohit Jindal for their friendship and support. A special thank to the memory of Lesiba Eli Bopape, whose genuine care for others and cheerfiil spirit will always be remembered. I would like to thank my good friends in the volleyball group who have brought me so much happiness and support, especially during the most intensive writing stage. I would like to express my gratitude to my family for their unwavering love and support. I am grateful to my parents, Lixin Zhang and Shiyun Zhu, for encouraging me to spread my wings, and for doing everything they could to help me pursue my dreams. I thank my sister, Ying Zhang, for being my best friend, study (and shopping) buddy, and most importantly, an inspiring scholar and historian of enormous potential. I reserve my last words to express my gratitude and love to my husband, Gao Yun, for his faith in me, constant support, and understanding, and for sharing every ups and downs with me throughout the process. viii TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ................................................................................................................... xi List of Figures ................................................................................................................. xii Introduction ...................................................................................................................... 1 References .............................................................................................................. 5 Essay 1: Bioeconomic Modeling for Natural Enemy-Adjusted Economic Threshold: An Application to Soybean Aphid 1.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 7 1.2 Soybean aphid and its natural enemies ............................................................ 9 1.3 Model of pest management ............................................................................ 'l O 1.4 Bioeconomic model of soybean aphid management ..................................... 13 1.5 Model estimation ........................................................................................... 21 1.6 Illustrative examples ...................................................................................... 27 1.7 Conclusion ..................................................................................................... 29 References ............................................................................................................ 32 Essay 2: Optimal Control of Soybean Aphid in the Presence of Natural Enemies 2.1 Introduction .................................................................................................... 48 2.1 Soybean aphid and its natural enemies .......................................................... 51 2.3 Bioeconomic optimization model .................................................................. 53 2.4 Numerical analysis ......................................................................................... 56 2.5 Sensitivity analysis ......................................................................................... 65 2.6 Conclusion ..................................................................................................... 68 References ............................................................................................................ 71 Essay 3: Spatially Optimal Habitat Management for Enhancing Natural Pest Control Services 3.1 Introduction .................................................................................................... 83 3.2 Conceptual model .......................................................................................... 87 3.3 Empirical model ............................................................................................. 92 3.4 Numerical analysis ....................................................................................... 100 3.5 Sensitivity analysis ....................................................................................... 107 3.6 Conclusion and future research needs .......................................................... 108 References .......................................................................................................... 1 13 Conclusions ................................................................................................................... 144 References .......................................................................................................... l 47 Appendix A: MatLab code for the optimal insecticide management model (Essay 2) ....................... 148 ix Appendix B: MatLab code for the habitat spatial optimization model (Essay 3) ............................... 153 Appendix C: Estimated relationship between the pest reduction impact and the proportion of non-crop habitats in the landscape ................................................................................................ 167 Appendix D: Proportion of change in variable costs of production due to the establishment of non-crop habitats (Lambda) .......................................................................................................... 168 Appendix E: Production costs by farming system and crop ............................................................... 171 Table 1.1: Table 1.2: Table 1.3: Table 1.4: Table 2.1: Table 2.2: Table 3.1: Table 3.2: LIST OF TABLES Parameters for the SBA population model ..................................................... 39 Parameters for the natural enemy population model ...................................... 40 Non-linear least squares estimation results from the reformulated restricted Cousens rectangular hyperbolic model .......................................................... 41 NEET illustration: population densities of SBA and natural enemies, harvest yields, and optimal spray decisions chosen for two initial values of S, (40 and 140 aphids/plant) given four values of NE 1 (0-4 NE/plant) (Daily predation rate=35 aphids/NE, initial maximum yield potential E1[y]=60 bu/ac) ........... 42 Values of parameters from Zhang (Essay l)’s model .................................... 76 Summary of sensitivity analysis results organized by ranges of initial SBA population density (Initial yield potential=40 bu/ac, daily predation rate=35 aphids/NE) ...................................................................................................... 77 Values of parameters used in the numerical analysis and their sources or estimations ................................................................................................... l 17 Summary of sensitivity analysis results (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel, and strip NCH) ................................................................................. l 18 xi LIST OF FIGURES Images in this thesis/dissertation are presented in color. Figure 1.1: Illustration of the advancement of biological dynamics within season ......... 43 Figure 1.2: Simulated predation-free daily SBA density (aphids/plant) from Costamagna et al. (2007b) model .................................................................. 44 Figure 1.3: Composition of ladybeetle species included to quantify natural enemy presence (Data were provided by Alejandro Costamagna, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, at the time the data were collected) ........................................................................................................ 45 Figure 1.4: Comparison of model prediction of untreated SBA densities during R] to R5 with field data for 2003 and 2005, KBS, Michigan. (Field data were provided by Alejandro Costamagna, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, at the time the data were collected.) ............................................ 46 Figure 1.5: Illustration of how optimal control path is reached for a given combination of initial values of pest density (S1),, natural enemy density (NE 1),, and maximum yield potential (E ,[y])k ................................................................................... 47 Figure 2.1: Optimal control paths for initial yield potentials of 40 bu/ac (a) and 60 bu/ac (b) at the mean daily predation rate of 35 aphids per natural enemy ............. 78 Figure 2.2: Optimal control paths for initial yield potentials of 40 bu/ac (a) and 60 bu/ac (b) at the minimum daily predation rate of 17 aphids per natural enemy ...... 79 Figure 2.3: Optimal control paths for initial yield potentials of 40 bu/ac (a) and 60 bu/ac (b) at the maximum daily predation rate of 52 aphids per natural enemy ..... 80 Figure 2.4: Value of producer return at initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac and daily predation rate of 35 aphids per natural enemy ............................................... 81 Figure 2.5: Value of one natural enemy per plant in stage R1 at daily predation rate of 35 aphids per natural enemy and initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac ................... 82 Figure 3.1: The distribution of land between non-crop habitats, impact zone, and no impact zone .................................................................................................. l 19 Figure 3.2a: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80X80 grid and with pro_NCH=0.l): Square.. 120 xii Figure 3.2b: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80XSO grid and with pro_NCH=0.l): Strip ..... 121 Figure 3.2c: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80X80 grid and with pro_NCH=O. l ): Archipelago ...................................................................................................................... 122 Figure 3.33: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200><200 grid): Cylindrical kernel (radius=100 m) .................................................................................. 123 Figure 3.3b: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200><200 grid): Laplace kernel (a=0.02 m") ...................................................................................... 124 Figure 3.3c: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200><200 grid): Gaussian kernel (0:80 m) ............................................................................................ 125 Figure 3.4: The relationship between the NCH area and the average pest reduction impact (Estimated from Bianchi and van der Werf, 2003) ...................................... 126 Figure 3.5(i)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400><400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Square ................................................................................................................ 127 Figure 3.5(i)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400><400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Strip .................................................................................................................... 128 Figure 3.5(i)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400><400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Archipelago ........................................................................................................ 129 Figure 3.5(ii)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=O.l in a 400X400 grid: Laplace kernel; Square .......................................................................................................... 130 Figure 3.5(ii)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with pr0p_NCH=0.l in a 400><400 grid: Laplace kernel; Strip .............................................................................................................. 131 Figure 3.5(ii)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400 x400 grid: Laplace kernel; Archipelago .................................................................................................. l 32 Figure 3.5(iii)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=O.l in a 400 X400 grid: Gaussian kernel; Square .......................................................................................................... 133 xiii Figure 3.5(iii)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCI-I=0.1 in a 400><4OO grid: Gaussian kernel; Strip .............................................................................................................. 134 Figure 3.5(iii)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400><400 grid: Gaussian kernel; Archipelago .................................................................................................. 1 35 Figure 3.6a: Illustration of assumed modes of machinery field operation (the number “1” represents one turn): Square ......................................................................... 136 Figure 3.6b: Illustration of assumed modes of machinery field operation (the number “1” represents one turn): Strip ............................................................................ 137 Figure 3.6c: Illustration of assumed modes of machinery field operation (the number “1” represents one turn): Archipelago ................................................................ 138 Figure 3.7: Estimated values of the percentage of change in variable costs of production for square and strip patterns ......................................................................... 139 Figure 3.8: Estimated values of the percentage of change in variable costs of production for archipelago pattern ................................................................................. 140 Figure 3.9: Proportion of change in net return to fixed factors (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel) ............................................................................................. 141 Figure 3.10: Proportion of change in net return to fixed factors for a conventional farm when change in variable costs of production is ignored (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel) .......................................................................... 142 Figure 3.11: The effect of distribution kernels on the relative performance of HM at medium pest infestation ............................................................................... 143 xiv Introduction Daily (1997) defines ecosystem services as the conditions and processes through which natural ecosystems, and the species that make them up, sustain and fulfill human life. Agricultural ecosystems are actively managed by humans to optimize provisioning ecosystem services for food, fiber, and fuel (MA, 2005). To do so, they depend upon a wide variety of supporting and regulating services such as soil fertility, natural control of crop pests and pollination as inputs to production (de Groot et al., 2002; MA, 2005; NRC, 2005), which directly translate to the profitability of farming as well as the social and environmental extemalities to and from agriculture. The control of pests by their natural enemies represents an important regulating ecosystem service that maintains the stability of agricultural ecosystems and has the potential to mitigate pest control costs (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Pimental et al., 1997). As the limitations and negative extemalities of chemical insecticides have become more obvious, the value of natural pest control services has increasingly been recognized (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997). In addition to the well-documented human health and environmental risks (Wilson and Tisdell, 2001), insecticide application in agriculture can damage the functioning of many ecosystem services. For instance, honeybees, which are vital for the pollination of crops, are affected by most of the insecticides used, causing agricultural losses due to reduction in insect pollination of crops (Pimentel et al., 1992). The flow of the natural pest control services critically depends on how agricultural ecosystems are managed and the diversity, composition, and functioning of the remaining ecosystems (Tilman, 1999). The functioning and viability of natural enemies can be damaged by chemically based pest management, which remains the dominant form of agricultural pest control. Use of broad-spectrum pesticides tends to severely damage populations of natural enemies, potentially exacerbating existing pest problems or even triggering the emergence of new pests (Calkins, 1983; Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Krishna et al., 2003). Habitat destruction and intensification of agricultural systems are destructive of natural pest control services (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997). Natural pest control in general is positively correlated to landscape complexity, which is chiefly characterized by the proportion, size, and spatial arrangement of non-crop habitats in the landscape (Bianchi et al., 2006; Steffan-Dewenter et al., 2002). These relationships and interactions can have potentially important economic implications for farm profitability and the management of this ecosystem service. The three essays of this dissertation focus on two integral management components: i) to conserve natural enemies so that they can effectively reduce pest populations, and ii) to enhance natural enemy populations so that more pest control services are available. The first component involves optimizing insecticide use to capitalize upon the natural pest control services—an integration of two alternative pest management mechanisms. Unfortunately, little attention has been given to the interaction or compatibility of the different technologies used in pest management (Thomas, 1999). Current chemical control practices typically don’t take into account the presence of natural enemies. Untimely application of broad-spectrum insecticides can decimate natural enemy populations. The non-target mortality effects of chemical insecticides on populations of natural enemies imply inefficiencies in insecticide use if unaccounted for in the treatment decision—an “opportunity cost” to producers in terms of foregone natural control services that would have been provided by existing natural enemies. As a result, farmers may invest in unwarranted insecticide application, potentially leading to excessive release of chemical pollutions. To achieve socially optimal insecticide application with natural enemies efficiently used, key ecological factors and interactions such as the predation effect of natural enemies on pests, the non-target mortality effect of insecticides on natural enemies, and the enhancing role of non-crop habitats on natural pest control services should be incorporated into decision making. Bioeconomic modeling of the behavior of ecological communities (pests, natural enemies, and crop plants) has the advantages of quantitatively describing biological processes and interactions and predicting their response to management decisions (King et al., 1993). Essay 1 develops a bioeconomic framework for optimal pest management that explicitly takes into account the population dynamics of natural enemies. The study develops a natural enemy-adjusted economic threshold that represents the pest population density threshold at which pesticide control becomes optimal in spite of the opportunity cost of injury to natural enemies of the target pest, whereas the conventional economic threshold is generally based on pest abundance and does not address natural enemy mortality or the impact of natural enemies on pest survival. Essay 2 applies the bioeconomic model developed in essay 1 for a simulation experiment on optimal control of soybean aphid, a new invasive pest of soybeans in the North Central region of the United States, taking into account the contribution of major natural enemies such as ladybeetles. In particular, the analysis addresses how the optimal number and timing of insecticide applications would be different if the presence of natural enemies is accounted for in the decision making. The study also performs preliminary assessment of the economic value of the natural control services of ladybeetles in suppressing soybean aphid damage to private producers. In the long run, effective agroecosystem management will demand more of managers than simply to reduce the non-target effect of pesticides on natural enemies. Habitat management that improves landscape complexity can potentially benefit natural enemies and in most cases result in enhanced biological control of pests (Thies and Tschamtke, 1999; Wilby and Thomas, 2002; Cardinale et al., 2003; Ostman et al., 2003; Thies et al., 2003). The second component of the management of natural pest control services thus moves beyond insecticide use thresholds to develop sustainable agricultural land use guidelines for explicit management of habitat for the natural enemies of agricultural pests. Essay 3 develops a spatial optimization model to explore economically optimal spatial habitat configuration for natural enemies of crop pests. The central question is to what extent and under what production systems that habitat management offers private producers the economic incentives for adoption. Each of the three essays stands alone as individual paper but as a group, they are designed jointly to contribute to the economic literature on optimal pest management by incorporating the important ecological function of natural pest control into decision making. References Bianchi, F.J.J.A., C.J.H. Booij, and T. Tschamtke. 2006. “Sustainable pest regulation in agricultural landscapes: a review on landscape composition, biodiversity and natural pest control.” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London Series B- Biological Sciences 273: 1 71 5-1 727. Calkins, CO. 1983. “Research on exotic pests.” In C.L. Wilson and C.L. Graham, ed. Exotic Plant Pests and North American Agriculture. New York: Academic Press, pp. 321-359. Cardinale, B.J., C.T. Harvey, K. Gross, and AR. Ives. 2003. “Biodiversity and biocontrol: emergent impacts of a multi-enemy assemblage on pest suppression and crop yield in an agroecosystem.” Ecology Letters 6: 857-65. Daily, G. 1997. Nature ’s Services. Washington, DC: Island Press. Daily, G., and K. Ellison. 2002. The New Economy of Nature--The Quest to Make Conservation Profitable. Washington, DC: Island Press/Shearwater Books. de Groot, R.S., M.A. Wilson, and R.M.J. Boumans. 2002. “A typology for the classification, description and valuation of ecosystem functions, goods and services.” Ecological Economics 41:393-408. King, R.P., D.W. Lybecker, A. Regmi, and SM. Swinton. 1993. “Bioeconomic models of crop production systems: design, development, and use.” Review of Agricultural Economics. 15(2): 389-401 . Krishna, V.V., N.G. Byju, and S. Tamizheniyan. 2003. “Integrated pest management in Indian agriculture: a developing economic perspective.” In E.B. Radcliff and W.D. Hutchson, ed. [PM World Textbook. St. Paul MN: University of Minnesota. National Research Council (NRC). 2005. Valuing Ecosystem Services: Toward Better Environmental Decision-Making. Washington, DC: National Academies Press. Ostman, 0., B. Ekbom, and J. Bengtsson. 2003. “Yield increase attributable to aphid predation by ground-living polyphagous natural enemies in spring barley in Sweden.” Ecological Economics 45: 149-58. Pimentel, D., H. Acquay, M. Biltonen, P. Rice, M. Silve, J. Nelson, V. Lipner, S. Giordano, A. Horowitz, and M. D’amore. 1992. “Environmental and human costs of pesticide use.” Bioscience 42: 750-760. Pimentel, D., C. Wilson, C. McCullum, R. Huang, P. Dwen, J. Flack, Q. Tran, T. Saltman, and B. Cliff. 1997. “Economic and environmental benefits of biodiversity.” BioScience 47(1 1): 47-757. Steffan-Dewenter, 1., U. Munzenberg, C. Burger, C. Thies, and T. Tschamtke. 2002. “Scale-dependent effects of landscape context on three pollinator guilds.” Ecology 83(5): 1421-1432. Thies, C., I. Steffan-Dewenterk, and T. Tschamtke. 2003. “Effects of landscape context on herbivory and parasitism at different spatial scales.” Oikos 101: 18-25. Thies, C., and T. Tschamtke. 1999. “Landscape structure and biological control in agroecosystems.” Science 285(5429): 893-895. Thomas, MB. 1999. “Ecological approaches and the development of "truly integrated" pest management.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 96(May): 5944-5951. Tilman, D. 1999. “Global environmental impacts of agricultural expansion: The need for sustainable and efficient practices.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 96(May): 5995-6000. Wilby, A., and MB. Thomas. 2002. “Natural enemy diversity and pest control: patterns of pest emergence with agricultural intensification.” Ecology Letters 5: 353-60. Wilson, C., and C. Tisdell. 2001. “Why farmers continue to use pesticides despite environmental, health and sustainability costs.” Ecological Economics 39: 449- 462. Essay 1: Bioeconomic Modeling for Natural Enemy-Adjusted Economic Threshold: An Application to Soybean Aphid 1.1 Introduction The control of pests by their natural enemies represents an important ecosystem service that maintains the stability of agricultural ecosystems and has the potential to mitigate pest control costs (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Losey and Vaughan, 2006). In addition to the well-documented human health and environmental risks of applying broad-spectrum insecticides (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Thomas, 1999; Heimpel et al., 2004), another unwanted consequence is the decimation of ambient populations of natural enemies. Loss of natural enemies can exacerbate existing pest problems or even trigger the emergence of new pests (Calkins, 1983; Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Krishna et al., 2003). Such unintended effects reduce the cost-effectiveness of insecticides if unaccounted for in the treatment decision. These create an “opportunity cost” to producers in terms of foregone natural control services that would have been provided by existing natural enemies'. Bioeconomic modeling of the behavior of ecological communities has the advantages of quantitatively describing biological processes and interactions and predicting their response to management decisions (King et al., 1993). As such, it is an important tool for addressing such inefficiencies by offering decision rules that integrate natural control services into decision making. ‘ Insecticide resistance of pests constitutes a source of “opportunity cost” experienced directly by producers. Resistance typically takes multiple seasons to develop and poses less of an immediate problem for intra-seasonal decision-making as compared to the destruction of natural enemies, and thus is not addressed by this study. This study develops an intra-seasonal, dynamic bioeconomic optimization model to develop a natural enemy-adjusted economic threshold (NEET). The NEET is defined as the pest population density threshold at which pesticide control becomes optimal in spite of the opportunity cost of injury to natural enemies of the target pest. Using field data from Michigan collected under a multi-state soybean aphid USDA Risk Assessment and Mitigation Program (RAMP) project on “Soybean Aphid in the North Central US: Implementing 1PM at the Landscape Scale”, the model is applied to the case of soybean aphid (Aphis glycines, Matsumura) (SBA). While selective insecticides may reduce the risk on natural enemies, broad-spectrum insecticides have been shown to provide greater protection from SBA (O’Neal, 2007) and are likely to remain important options for pest managers. The central question, therefore, is to choose the optimal level of broad- spectrum insecticide use to conserve natural enemies of SBA to the extent that the economic benefit to the farmer outweighs the additional cost. While the conservation of natural enemy insects is likely to confer a wide range of social and environmental benefits, our model is focused on farrners’ private economic incentives for minimizing natural enemy mortality via optimizing the number and timing of insecticide applications, given a pre-determined dose and toxicity level and holding prices constant. Following this introduction section, we provide background information on the SBA problem and the role of natural enemies in SBA regulation (section 1.2). We review existing pest management models in section 1.3, followed by a presentation of our intra- seasonal, dynamic bioeconomic optimization model in section 1.4. In section 1.5, we report on parameter estimations and discuss model validation. We then present two numerical analysis examples in section 1.6 to illustrate how the model works. Finally, we highlight contributions of the model, identify limitations and suggest future research needs (section 1.7). 1.2 Soybean aphid and its natural enemies Soybean aphid is an invasive species that was first discovered in the North Central region of the United States in 2000. Within four years, it had spread to 21 states and south- central Canada (Landis et al., 2004). Not only is SBA capable of causing extensive damage to soybean yield with documented yield loss of up to 40% (DiFonzo and Hines, 2002), SBA outbreaks are also correlated with dramatic increases in virus incidence in vegetable crops (Alleman et al., 2002; Stevenson and Grau, 2003; Thompson and German, 2003; Fang et al., 1985; RAMP, 2006). Since its invasion, SBA has prompted farmers to perform extensive spray of soybean acreage, making it one of the key drivers of insecticide use in the region (Smith and Pike, 2002). For example, 42% of soybean acreage in Michigan and 30% in Minnesota were sprayed during the 2005 season, compared with less than 1% before SBA arrived in 1999 in North Central region states for which data are available (NASS, 2007). Existing natural enemy communities play a key role in suppressing SBA populations (Fox et al., 2004; Aponte and Calvin, 2004; Rutledge et al., 2004; Landis et al., 2004; Costamagna and Landis, 2006; Berg, 1997). Natural enemies of SBA include 22 predator species (Rutledge et al., 2004), 6 parasitoid species (Kaiser et al., 2007), and several species of fungi that cause disease in aphids (Nielsen and Hajek, 2005). In particular, generalist predators (mainly ladybeetles, Coccinellidae) provide strong, season- long suppression, protecting soybean biomass and yield from SBA damage (Costamagna et al., 2007a). However, most insect natural enemies are susceptible to the major insecticides used to treat SBAZ. Evidence from Iowa indicates that insecticides applied in early season can actually result in greater SBA population later (O’Neal, 2007), undermining the cost-effectiveness of insecticide investment. Although general recommendations stress the need for assessing field situation with respect to natural enemies before spraying (e.g., Smith and Pike, 2002; NSRL, 2002; NCPMC, 2005), the current extension treatment threshold recommendation relies solely on aphid density observation, whereas no applicable decision guide has been offered to producers to conserve and capitalize on the pest regulation services supplied by ambient natural enemies. 1.3 Models of pest management The existing models of pest management threshold decision rules have been developed on two fronts: the economic threshold (ET) model by entomologists and the marginal analysis model by economists (Mumford and Norton, 1984). Our critique of the literature necessarily focuses on the economic approach, but also discusses the evolving of the ET concept in the entomological literature and how the entomologically-based ET model is linked to (and different from) the economic approach. Introduced as a crucial component of Integrated Pest Management (1PM) by Stern et al. (1959) and having since become recognized as an operational decision rule (Mumford and Norton, 1984), ET in the 1PM literature refers to the pest population density at which control measures should be initiated to prevent an increasing pest 2 Christine DiFonzo, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, personal communications, October 4, 2005 and March 2, 2006. 10 population from reaching the economic injury level (Pedigo et al., 1986). With economic injury level (EIL) defined as the lowest population density that will cause economic damage and given by the equation EIL=C/VIDK (where C is the cost of chemical control ($/ac), Vthe value of a crop ($/ac), I the injury inflicted by the pest, D the damage response by the crop to that injury, and K the proportionate reduction in pest attack conferred by the control action), ET can be derived from EIL by tracking backwards in time according to the population dynamics of the pest given some lag time needed for farmers to take action (Pedigo et al., 1986). Integrating the economic concepts of optimization and marginality, Headley (I972) redefined the ET as the optimal (net-retum-maximizing) pest population density where the marginal value product of damage control equals the marginal cost of control. Hall and Norgaard (1973) improved Headley’s framework by developing a more general model which considers the optimal timing and quantity of a single pesticide application. Even though they used time variables in their models, the models are essentially static because present control decisions do not affect future opportunities (Bor, 1995; Kamien and Schwartz, 1981). Consideration for multiple treatments later makes it necessary to design an approach for achieving optimality over time, triggering the incorporation of dynamic aspects of pest management into ET development (e.g., Talpaz and Borosh, 1974, Zacharias and Grube, 1986, Harper et al., 1994, and Bor, 1995). The suppression services of natural enemies, as well as the unintended effect of broad-spectrum insecticides on the population of natural enemies, however, have not been included. In a single treatment (i.e., static) framework, under certain circumstances (i.e., parameters C, V, I, D, and K are independent of pest population, and K is fixed for a ll treatment) the entomological concept of ET can potentially achieve optimality in an economic sense because the EIL is essentially determined by the economically optimal condition of marginal value produced equal to marginal factor cost. The entomological model of ET, however, is not capable of providing optimal treatment solutions when multiple treatments are required during the season. In the entomological literature, improvements have been made to the current ET approach that is generally based on pest abundance and does not address natural enemy mortality or the impact of natural enemies on pest survival (Musser et al., 2006) to incorporate the dynamic impact of natural enemies on ET (e.g., Brown, 1997, Musser et al., 2006, Tang et al., 2005). These modeling efforts attempt to address the inefficiency raised in situations where if pest population grth rates are substantially reduced by natural enemies, there may be enough population regulation to prevent pests from reaching the EIL, in which case treatment triggered by ET density would not guarantee yield benefit equal to the cost of control (Ragsdale et al., 2007). Field observation in Minnesota shows that this outcome indeed happened in several SBA-infested field trials in 2005. Musser et al. (2006) propose a framework for the development of dynamic ET that moves up or down with changes in biological mortality caused by natural enemies in the period between ET determination and EIL realization, offering potential efficiency gains from reducing insecticide use. Despite the improvements, these models work with the same static EIL that is not determined based on the economic method of optimization. Thus, a dynamic bioeconomic model that models the net-retum-maximizing behavior of economic agents and explicitly factors in the presence of natural enemies is needed. 12 1.4 Bioeconomic model of soybean aphid management Our bioeconomic optimization model assumes that a soybean producer maximizes the returns over variable costs of pest control, subject to three biological constraints: i) population dynamics of SBA as affected by both chemical control and natural enemy suppression, ii) population dynamics of natural enemies that is coupled with prey density and subject to the toxicity of SBA insecticides, and iii) a yield response function that describes the relationship between pest density and yield potential. A stage-based dynamic framework similar to that of Harper et al. (1994) is adopted. Specifically, the biological components evolve over five discrete time periods corresponding to five growth stages of soybean plant within a growing season (Figure 1.1). The model incorporates factors such as the contribution of natural enemies to pest regulation, the positive impact of prey consumption on natural enemy population, and the natural enemy mortality caused by SBA insecticides, whose economic implications to optimal control have not been considered in the existing literature. The outcome of the dynamic optimization model prescribes natural enemy-adjusted optimal number and timing of insecticide application. Olson and Badibanga (2005) developed a bioeconomic model to evaluate and compare the net returns of four potential thresholds (3, 100, 250, and 500 aphids per plant) to treat SBA and found that the 3 aphids/plant threshold a dominant strategy regardless of initial infestation date and aphid growth rate. Without accounting for natural enemies of SBA, the threshold for spraying was 99% below the prevailing North Central states extension recommendation of 250 aphids per plant (Ragsdale et al., 2007). I3 The current model differs from Olson and Badibanga (2005)’s model in three major aspects. First, our model is intended for implementing dynamic optimization analysis, which prescribes an optimal control path for given initial status of populations of the pest and natural enemies over a finite planning horizon. In other words, after one assessment of the infested field, we predict the number and timing of treatments for the entire season, whereas the decision rule developed by Olson and Badibanga (2005) requires pest population to be monitored constantly and treatment is triggered whenever pest population reaches certain threshold. Second, limited by insufficient data, Olson and Badibanga (2005) adopt a partially developed SBA population growth model. Specifically, the growth of the aphid population follows an exponential function with fixed population growth rate and is forced to decline once the population enters a pre- determined maximum range. F or the population dynamics of SBA, we adopt a daily- based SBA growth model developed by Costamagna et al. (2007b) that incorporates a linearly decreasing growth rate into an exponential grth model to account for the impact of host plant phenology, which has been shown as an important factor affecting aphid population growth (Rossing et al., 1994; Williams et al., 1999). The model has been demonstrated to accurately predict SBA population dynamics in soybeans in Michigan fields, including the population decline towards the end of the season (Costamagna et al., 2007b). Third, since non-linearity is particularly common in yield damage functions (Swinton et al., 1994), we adopt the Cousens (I 985) rectangular hyperbolic functional form for the yield response function and select among alternative models the one that fits our data best. Most importantly, we include natural control 14 services explicitly in decision making so as to improve the efficiency of insecticide use by private producers with potential socially desirable outcome. The system of soybean growth stages divides plant development into vegetative (V) and reproductive (R) stages (Pedersen, 2004). Our model focuses on the five earlier reproductive stages, RI through R5 (indexed by discrete t and t=l , 2, 3, 4, 5), during which period soybeans are most susceptible to SBA damage (Jameson-Jones, 2005). The following table describes the various stages. Vegetative Stages Reproductive Stages RI (beginning flowering) VE (emergence) R2 (full flowering) VC (unrolled unifoliolate leaves) R3 (beginning pod) V1 (first trifoliolate) R4 (full pod) V2 (second trifoliolate) R5 (beginning seed) V3 (third trifoliolate) R6 (full seed) V(n) (nth trifoliolate) R7 (beginning maturity) V6 (flowering will soon start) R8 (full maturity) Source: Pedersen, 2004 Farmers tend not to practice variable rate pesticide application due both to applicator time constraints and label rates being required for manufacturers to guarantee efficacy. Therefore, we define the control decision in each stage as a binary choice, denoted by x, (x,=l for spray at fixed label-recommended rates, and x,=0 for no spray at stage t). We assume that no more than one spray may occur in each stage and that the predicted yield upon stage R5 is carried through to harvest so that SBA control is only meaningful during stages R1 to R4. The growth of SBA population over the five reproductive stages of the soybean plant is given by: 51+] = (St "kS,t ‘xt 'St)+"gt '(St "kS,t ’xt 'St)—P"t (NE, _kNE,t 'xt 'NEt) (I) (t=1, 2, 3, 4) where S,. 1 denotes SBA density per plant at stage t+1, NE,denotes density of natural 15 enemies per plant at stage t, k5,, and km, represent mortality rates of SBA and natural enemies from insecticide application, respectively, ng, denotes net growth rate of SBA population in the absence of “outside” regulation, and pr, is the aggregate predation rate per NE unit per time period (stage). While an abundant number of existing natural enemy communities jointly contribute to suppressing SBA population in soybeans (Fox and Landis, 2002), the role of generalist predators (mainly Coccinellidae, or lady beetles) is particularly important (Costamagna et al., 2007a) due to their high abundance in both number and overall suppression effectiveness (Costamagna, 2006). We therefore focus on the ladybeetle family in our quantification of the natural enemy presence by aggregating populations of major ladybeetle species. The adoption of an aggregate population level is underlined by the following considerations. First, the major regulating species vary both temporally and spatially in terms of the suppression services they provide. For instance, in Michigan, Harmonia axyridis (multi-colored Asian ladybeetle) and Coccinella septempunctata (seven-spotted ladybeetle) provide sequential pest suppression mid season through harvest, with seven-spotted ladybeetle dominating the mid season and multi-colored Asian ladybeetle dominating the late season (McKeown, 2003). Data collected at the Kellogg Biological Station (KBS) Long-terrn Ecological Research site at Hickory Comers in Kalamazoo County, Michigan, show that the high populations of seven- spotted ladybeetle may have aided in delaying SBA colonization of the KBS site (McKeown, 2003). The spread of SBA later in the season was subsequently further hindered by the high prevalence of multi-colored Asian ladybeetle (McKeown, 2003). It is therefore difficult to quantitatively differentiate their individual contributions. Second, 16 detailed data on the biology and ecology of major predator species such as multi-colored Asian ladybeetle are lacking, limiting our capability to develop reliable population models for individual species. Ideally, a set of weighting coefficients should be developed to account for the relative contribution of each included species. In the current study, however, such information is not available, and we treat each species as equal in their contribution to the aggregate population level. We adopt a dynamic Lotka-Volterra predator-prey model (Lotka, 1925; Volterra, 1926) to describe changes in the population density of natural enemies coupled with prey consumption over discrete time periods. Denoted by NEH], the population density of natural enemies at stage H] is given by: NEt+I = (NE, “kit/5,1 -x, 'NEt) +dt '(NEt "kNE,t 'xt 'NEt) (2) +bt '(St _kS,t ’xt 'St)'(NEt _kNE,t 'xt ‘NED (Fl, 2, 3)3 where d, (<0) is the natural net decline rate that NE would suffer in the absence of prey and b, (>0) is interpreted as the reproduction rate of NE per prey encountered (Sharov, 1996, 1997, 1999). Farmers often make sequential predictions on achievable yield over the course of the growing season based on perception of initial yield potential, pest infestation and other factors such as weather. We offer a conceptual model of yield-pest interaction that is consistent with the process for updating yield potential described above. We express 3 The natural enemy model is estimated for stages R1 to R3 to predict population up to stage R4 (NE... 1..) , which in turn affects SBA population in stage R5—the last stage in which SBA can cause damage to harvest yield in our model. Therefore, we do not need t=4 for the natural enemy model. 17 the expected yield potential at stage t+l , denoted by Emjy], as a function of expected yield potential at stage t (E,[y]) and pest population density at t (S,): and Elly] = Th. Esly] = yh where )7}, is maximum (pest-free) potential yield or average historical yield upon which the season’s first prediction is based, and the actual yield at harvest, yh, is assumed to be equal to yield potential evaluated at the final reward stage T + 1=6. In a non-linear yield- pest interaction model such as the Cousens (1985) rectangular hyperbolic model, the conceptual model can be implemented by replacing the parameter that represents maximum yield with the fitted value of yield potential obtained in the previous period (E,[y]) to render the following reformulated Cousens rectangular hyperbolic model: Et+1IYI = Elly] - (1 - ) (4) 1 + 77, - S, / 0, where n, denotes the proportion of yield lost per unit of pest population and 6, denotes the maximum proportional yield loss to pest damage (O_<_ 9,31). We assume that a producer maximizes his/her expected return over variable costs of pest management (derived by subtracting total SBA control cost from soybean revenue realized at harvest) over a sequence of control decisions within the growing season, subject to biological constraints describing pest population, natural enemy population, and crop yield potential. Denoted by J, the objective function can be written as: T=5 J = Mgfs [p-yh — Z ctx. >1 (5) (x, },=_1 t=l 18 subject to equations (1), (2), and (3) with 1,, NE 1, and y, are given. {xt },T:15 represents a sequence of control actions over the five time periods, p denotes output price, and c(x,) denotes control cost, including the cost of pest scouting to provide the basis for control decisions. No discount factor is included for this single-season optimization problem due to its relatively short duration. Using the method of dynamic programming (Bellman, 1957), we illustrate some of the analytical solutions to the dynamic optimization problem. We adopt a general form for the yield response function because expressions of analytical solution when non- linearity presents are extremely lengthy and thus tend to hide the intuition we would like to highlight. Since the return over variable costs of control being maximized does not realize until the final reward period (T +1=6) and the control variable is binary, we have dichotomous, as opposed to continuous, optimal value functions that have to be tied to expected harvest yield, E6[y] or yh. We solve the Bellman’s equation recursively from the terminal period (T =5), during which time no control is actually necessary (i.e., x; = 0 ), so the optimal value function that describes the maximum expected reward for taking action x; = 0 is V; =P‘EclyI=P'f(E51ylaSS) (6) Bellman’s equation for t=4 is: V4 = Max [—c(x4)+V5*] (7) x4=1 or 0 19 Assuming constant control cost c(x,) = E for each period4, we iterate on Bellman’s equation to get the first order condition (F 0C) for maximization: OX4 355 OX4 which gives the following condition: __ 3E 8E -0 + P736319? ' kNE,4NE4 = P 6.69M ks,4S4(1+ "84) (8) 5 The two terms on the left-hand side (LHS) of (8) indicate the full marginal factor cost (MF C) of x4 (the sum of control cost and the value of natural SBA suppression lost due to control action at t=4), whereas the term on the right-hand side (RHS) represents the marginal value product (MVP) of x4. The optimal solution for x4 is thus determined by the following conditions: (I If "pmks 4S4(I +ng4) 26-paE6Ly] pr-kNE 4NE4 OI' MVPx 2 MFCx . as5 ’ as5 ’ 4 4 x4 :4 0 if —paE6[y]kS 484(1+ng4)‘NE4\_\ ' ’I . II I I, .\ Control Spray? '\,” Spray? X" Spray? 1‘," Spray? '\. decisions C I \.\[: I \.\C I \.\- \\ x 'x x 'x x 'x '24 Yield E A E """"""" _.A E ' A E A E A potential ’M—’ 234—» 3M —-> 4l.VI—-* 5M ——9 ynarvest ..... , Reproduction of NE due to SBA consumption —--.+ Predation of NE on SBA ................ , Yield damage by SBA _p Mortality by insecticides Figure 1.1: Illustration of the advancement of biological dynamics within season 43 R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 W W j/ 25000 20000 1 10000 I; 5000 If 04M. 7/5/05 7/12/05 7/19/05 7/26/05 8/2/05 8/9/05 8/16/05 Aphid density liliirtrrrfirT r1 + Model predicted daily population + Mean population of stage Figure 1.2: Simulated predation-free daily SBA density (aphids/plant) from Costamagna et al. (2007b) model 44 Year=2003 I Harmonia axyridis larvae I Harmonia axyridis adult I: Coleomegilla rmculata adult 1: Coccinella septerrpunctata larvae . I Coccinella septerrpunctata adult ‘ Year=2005 51% I Harmonia axyridis adult I Harmonia axyridis larvae D Coccinella septen'punctata adult I: Coccinella septempunctata larvae I Cycloneda rrunda adult I cycloneda rmnda larvae I Hippodam'a convergens adult I: Coleomegilla rmculata adult Figure 1.3: Composition of ladybeetle species included to quantify natural enemy presence (Data were provided by Alejandro Costamagna, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, at the time the data were collected) 45 Aphid density R4 R5 R1 R2 R3 + KBS data 2003 (S1=50,NE1=1.5) +Model prediction (S1=50,NE1=1.5) + KBS data 2005 (S1=70,NE1=2.5) -—)lt— Model prediction (S1=70,NE1=2.5) Figure 1.4: Comparison of model prediction of untreated SBA densities during R1 to R5 with field data for 2003 and 2005, KBS, Michigan. (Field data were provided by Alejandro Costamagna, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, at the time the data were collected.) 46 Starting Control Yields Returns over variable values paths (CP) resulted costs of control (NR) CPI (Vharvest)ijk iCPI NR1 CPZ (,VharvesOijk iCPZ NR2 Pest density (S 1), + . NE density (NE 1)‘ —- . =* a . Optimal control path= Max. yield ’ , ' , ary maXINerNRre} P0terltial (E1 [.ka CPI” O’harvest)ijk ICPle NR1“ Figure 1.5: Illustration of how optimal control path is reached for a given combination of initial values of pest density (51),, natural enemy density (NE 1),, and maximum yield potential (E 1M), 47 Essay 2: Optimal Control of Soybean Aphid in the Presence of Natural Enemies 2.1 Introduction Natural enemies provide an important ecosystem service of pest population suppression that maintains the stability of agricultural systems and potentially mitigates producers’ pest control costs (Naylor and Ehrlich, 1997; Losey and Vaughan, 2006). While the various approaches to biological control, including importation (or classical biological control), augmentation and conservation, all directly and purposefully use the natural control services (Barbosa and Braxton, 1993), integrating available natural control services into the decision-making of chemical control offers an important approach to improving the economic efficiency of insecticide use with potentially socially desirable outcomes. Focusing on the management of soybean aphid (Aphis glycines, Matsumura) (SBA), a new pest of soybeans in the North Central region of the United States, this study assesses how predation by natural enemies of SBA (mainly ladybeetles, Coccinellidae) contributes to optimal insecticide strategies. In the process, it also provides a lower bound estimate of the value of natural pest control services. Current chemical pest control practices typically do not take into account the presence of natural enemies. Untimely application of broad-spectrum insecticides can decimate natural enemy populations, potentially exacerbating existing pest problems or even triggering the emergence of new pests (Calkins, 1983; Naylor and Ehrlich, I997; Krishna et al., 2003). Such unintended effects imply inefficiencies in insecticide use if unaccounted for in the treatment decision—an “opportunity cost” to producers in terms of 48 foregone natural control services that would have been provided by existing natural enemies. Economic threshold (ET) refers to the optimal (net-retum-maximizing) pest population density where the marginal value product of damage control equals the marginal cost of control (Headley, 1972). The current ET concept is generally based on pest abundance and does not address natural enemy mortality or the impact of natural enemies on pest survival (Musser et al., 2006). Zhang (Essay 1) develops an intra- seasonal, dynamic bioeconomic optimization model that explicitly includes the predation effect of natural enemies on the target pest and demonstrates that the incorporation of natural pest control services into pest management threshold decision rules can potentially lead to reduction in insecticide use. This study applies the bioeconomic optimization model developed in Zhang (Essay 1) to i) identify optimal insecticide strategies for the control of SBA, taking into account the presence of natural enemies, and ii) provide preliminary assessment of the economic value of the SBA biological control services to private producers. The results suggest optimal SBA density as observed upon the initial decision point for pest control over the course of pest management, at which the prescribed control strategy is optimal despite the opportunity cost of natural enemy mortality due to insecticides. The estimated values are conservative, because they take into account only farmers’ private profitability benefits from optimizing the number and timing of broad-spectrum insecticide applications in the presence of natural enemies. A full accounting of the natural pest control services would also include potential social and environmental benefits (such as averted human health risks and environmental pollution 49 due to pesticides), which are likely to justify further reduced levels of insecticide use and higher economic value of natural pest control services. There have been two general types of valuation studies that assess the benefits of natural control services: 1) ex post impact assessment of classical biological control projects that look at the economic benefit of artificial introduction or massive release of natural enemies (Hill and Greathead, 2000), and ii) calculation of the aggregate annual monetary value of averted crop losses as a result of pest population suppression by extant natural enemies (e.g., Losey and Vaughan, 2006; Pimentel et al., 1997). This study focuses on the natural pest control services supplied by existing natural enemies. To calculate the aggregate annual monetary value of natural pest control services, existing studies typically start by estimating the total cost of pest damage resulted from all pest control mechanisms and then attribute a fraction of the total pest control benefit to natural enemies. For instance, Pimentel et al. (1997) estimated that natural enemies provide approximately $100 billion worth of pest control worldwide per year (about 60% of $156 billion total averted pest control cost a year), whereas Losey and Vaughan (2006) estimated the value of natural control to be $4.5 billion annually for the US. While these aggregate values provide snapshots on the possible magnitude of the benefit from natural enemies of crop pests humans enjoy, they ignore local context (e.g., pest species, pest pressure, existing natural enemy level, the value of protected yield, cost, effectiveness, and availability of alternative pest control mechanisms), and thus are rather uninforrnative for the producer-level management of this ecosystem service. Natural pest control services as regulating ecosystem services (MA, 2005) can be valued indirectly via their contribution as inputs to the biological production of marketed 50 products. Thus, their partial economic value can be inferred from the price of marketed products (Swinton and Zhang, 2005). In this study, model results will compare producer returns over variable costs of insecticide management with and without accounting for the presence of natural enemies. The results will be used to make a preliminary estimate of the incremental return over variable costs of control resulting from an additional natural enemy in the system given a set of economic and biological conditions. Following this introduction section, we provide background information on the SBA problem and the role of natural enemies in its regulation in section 2.2. We then briefly introduce the bioeconomic optimization model adopted in section 2.3. In section 2.4, we present numerical results from the dynamic optimization analysis for single season SBA management and the estimated economic value of natural enemies that attack SBA. Section 2.5 reports findings from a sensitivity analysis of key parameters. Finally, we highlight main findings, identify applications for the effects of natural enemy populations on optimal SBA control, and suggest future research directions (section 2.6). 2.2 Soybean aphid and its natural enemies Soybean aphid is an invasive species that was first discovered in the North Central region of the United States in 2000. Within four years, it had spread to 21 states and south- central Canada (Landis et al., 2004). Not only is SBA capable of causing extensive damage to soybean yield with documented yield loss of up to 40% (DiFonzo and Hines, 2002), SBA outbreaks are also correlated with dramatic increases in virus incidence in vegetable crops (Alleman et al., 2002; Stevenson and Grau, 2003; Thompson and German, 2003; Fang et al., 1985; RAMP, 2006). Since its invasion, SBA has prompted 51 extensive spray of soybean acreage, which had previously required negligible insecticide use in the region (Smith and Pike, 2002). For example, 42% of soybean acreage in Michigan and 30% in Minnesota were sprayed during the 2005 season, compared with less than 1% before SBA arrived in 1999 in North Central region states for which data are available (NASS, 2007). Existing natural enemy communities play a key role in suppressing SBA populations (Fox et al., 2004; Aponte and Calvin, 2004; Rutledge et al., 2004; Landis et al., 2004; Costamagna and Landis, 2006; Berg, 1997). Natural enemies of SBA include 22 predator species (Rutledge et al., 2004), 6 parasitoid species (Kaiser et al., 2007), and several species of fungi that cause disease in aphids (Nielsen and Hajek, 2005). In particular, generalist predators (mainly ladybeetles, Coccinellidae) provide strong, season- long suppression, protecting soybean biomass and yield from SBA damage (Costamagna et al., 2007). However, most insect natural enemies are susceptible to the major insecticides used to treat SBA1 . Evidence from Iowa indicates that insecticides applied in early season can actually result in greater SBA population later (O’Neal, 2007), undermining the cost-effectiveness of insecticide investment. Although general recommendations stress the need for assessing the field situation with respect to natural enemies before spraying (e.g., Smith and Pike, 2002; NSRL, 2002; NCPMC, 2005), the current extension treatment threshold recommendation relies solely on aphid density observation. However, it was developed from field data where natural enemies were probably present, so their effect is likely to be implicit in the threshold recommendation. ' Christine DiFonzo, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, personal communications, October 4, 2005 and March 2, 2006. 52 Up to now, producers have not been offered decision rule that explicitly accounts for the pest regulation services supplied by ambient natural enemies. 2.3 Bioeconomic optimization model Using field trail data from Michigan collected during 2003 and 2005 under a multi-state soybean aphid USDA Risk Assessment and Mitigation Program (RAMP) project on “Soybean Aphid in the North Central US: Implementing [PM at the Landscape Scale”, Zhang (Essay 1) develops an intra-seasonal, dynamic bioeconomic optimization model for SBA management over five time periods that correspond to the five reproductive stages of soybean plant growth, R1 through R5, during which soybeans are most susceptible to SBA damage (Jameson-Jones, 2005). The model assumes that a producer chooses the optimal control action (spray or no spray) at each decision point (t) to maximize end-of-season return over variable costs of control, subject to biological constraints describing the dynamics of pest population (5,), natural enemy population (NE,), and expected crop yield potential (E,[y]). Denoted by J, the objective function over the finite time horizon covering stages R1 to R5 can be written as: T=5 J= M455 [p-yh—thxm (1) {xt}t=-I [=1 subject to . 77t'St E =E - 1————— 2 1) t+lIJ’I ,[y] ( 1+771'Sr/9z) ( ) and E][y] = y'h,E6[y] = yh, t=l, 2, 3, 4, 5 10S”, =(1+ng.)-(S.—ks,-x.-S.>—pr.(Na-km-x.-NE.>.2=I.2. 3.4 (3) 53 iii) NE,+1 = (1 +d,)-(NE, —kNE,, ~x, - NE,)+b, (3, —k5,, -x, .s,)-(NE, —kNE,, -x, ~NE,) i=1, 2, 32 (4) iv) S1, NE], and Elfy] are given where p = output price x, = binary choice for control. x,=l for spray at fixed label-recommended rates at stage t, and x,=0 for no spray c(x,) = control cost at stage t, including the cost of pest scouting to provide the basis for control decisions S, = population density of SBA per plant at stage t NE, = population density of natural enemies per plant at stage t k5,, = mortality rate of SBA from insecticide application km, = mortality rate of natural enemies from insecticide application d, = natural net decline rate natural enemies would suffer in the absence of prey b, = the reproduction rate of natural enemies per prey encountered ng, = net growth rate of SBA population in the absence of “outside” regulation pr, = predation rate per natural enemy unit per stage E,[y] = expected yield potential at stage t n, = proportion of yield lost per unit of pest population 6, = maximum proportional yield loss to pest damage (056, El) y, = pest-free yield potential or average historical yield upon which the season’s first prediction is based 2 The model predicts population of natural enemies up to stage R4, which in turn affects SBA population in stage R5, the last stage when SBA can cause yield damage. 54 y), = actual yield at harvest (assumed to be equal to yield potential evaluated at stage T+ 1=6) Table 2.1 reports the values of parameters from Zhang (Essay 1)’s model. A few key points deserve note. First, the model assumes that no more than one spray may occur in each stage and that the predicted yield upon stage R5 is carried through to harvest so that SBA control is only meaningful during stages R1 to R4. Second, the quantification of the natural enemy presence is focused on major generalist predator species of the ladybeetle family, due to their high abundance in both number and overall suppression effectiveness (Costamagna, 2006). Populations of major ladybeetle species are aggregated, including Harmonia axyridis (multi-colored Asian ladybeetle) adult and larva, Coccinella septempunctata adult and larva, Coleomegilla maculata adult, C ycloneda munda adult, Cycloneda munda larva, and Hippodamia convergens adult. Third, based on findings from the biological literature and field observation of species composition, the model proposes an approximate range for the weighted average predation rate of SBA by ladybeetles: 17 to 52 aphids eaten per ladybeetle per day, which gives a mean consumption rate of 35 aphids/day per ladybeetle. The per stage predation rate pr, is then computed by multiplying daily predation rate by the number of days in a given stage (Table 2.1). Fourth, for price and cost parameters, we use a long-term soybean trend price of $6.9/bu and a treatment cost of $12.2/ac for the RAMP Best Management Practice treatment using pesticide Lambda-cyhalothrin (Warrior with Zeon Technology®) at 3.2 oz/ac (Song etal., 2006). A break-down of the cost includes $7/ac insecticide cost, $2/ac for scouting, and approximately $3.2/ac for spraying (Song et al., 2006). Finally, it is 55 assumed that insecticide will kill 99% of both SBA and natural enemies at each application during the season. Estimated values of parameters in Zhang (Essay 1) that are statistically significant are used directly in the numerical optimization analysis of this study with the exception of ”2, the proportion of yield lost per unit of pest population in stage R2, which is estimated to be negative, suggesting a “compensation” yield response relationship between pest injury and crop yield potential in R2 (Pedigo et al., 1986). While this estimation is theoretically possible (Pedigo et al., 1986; Tammes, 1961; Fenemore, 1982), field observations in Michigan do not show evidence of such compensation3. Thus, we assume that yield potential in stage R2 is not responsive to pest injury (i.e., n2=0) in the numerical exercise. For parameters that are found insignificant in their respective models, we use zeros instead of the estimated values in the numerical optimization analysis. 2.4 Numerical analysis The Optimizing simulation approach We adopt an optimizing simulation approach to solving the dynamic optimization problem numerically, within a solution space that is relevant to field observations made in Michigan soybean fields (see MatLab code in Appendix A). The approach is essentially an integration of two components: 1) a simulation routine to predict the economic outcome of each scenario, and ii) a selection routine to choose the control strategy (i.e., control path) that yields the best economic outcome. The algorithm of the approach is analogous to that of “DDPSOLVE”, a dynamic programming computer 3 Christine DiFonzo, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, personal communication, July 6, 2007. 56 program developed by Miranda and F ackler (2002) but with two major improvements: i) it allows the biological transition equations to contain stage-specific parameters, and ii) it significantly reduces computational expenses and thus enables us to use smaller and more accurate value intervals and wider ranges of possible initial values for the biological state variables. Specifically, the optimization is carried out as following: 0 Define space matrices for initial values of state variables S, and NE,: i) 31 possible values for S1 (0:5: I 50) (meaning a range of 0 to 150 aphids on average per plant with an interval of 5 in R1), and ii) 9 possible values for NE 1 (0:0.5z4). These ranges are chosen to reflect field observations of population densities of SBA and natural enemies in stage R1 in field trials in Michigan“. 0 Consider 11 scenarios for maximum (pest-free) yield potential (E1[y]) that are consistent with common Michigan yield levels (40:2:60) (MSU Field Crops AOE Team, 2002) and 3 scenarios for daily ladybeetle predation rate (pr,) (minimum, mean, and maximum of 17, 35, and 52 aphids per ladybeetle per day, respectively) to account for uncertainties in these parameter values. 0 Specify 16 distinct possible control paths, each representing a unique sequence of five control choices made over the periods R1-R5 with the optimal control action in the last period R5 always being “no control” (i.e., x5 =0 known). For each of the 33 maximum yield potential-predation rate scenarios (3*1 l=33 scenarios), we compare the predicted returns over variable costs of control from the 16 control paths for each of the 279 combinations of initial values of population densities of SBA and natural enemies (31*9=279). The total number of simulations to run therefore amounts to 4 Michigan field data for 2003 and 2005 provided by Christine DiFonzo and Alejandro Costamagna, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University. 57 147,312 (33*279*l6=147,312). In each simulation, the control path that yields the highest value of return over variable costs is designated the optimal control path. By defining relevant ranges for the initial values of population densities of SBA and natural enemies and scenarios for maximum yield potential and predation rate, we delimit a relevant sub-space within the full optimization solution space, effectively reducing the computational expense. Certainly, the smaller the intervals are, the more accurate are the predictions. The analysis covers sufficiently wide ranges of relevant initial values of biological state variables with reasonably small intervals. Numerical results For this deterministic, discrete and finite time horizon problem, the dynamic optimization model predicts the sequence of control actions that would be optimal for the entire season given initial values of the population densities of SBA and its natural enemies. Because the model is deterministic, its results follow from field scouting information once in the initial period of stage R1. To illustrate key results fiom the optimization analysis, we plot predicted optimal control paths against values of population densities of SBA (SI) and natural enemies (NE 1) in stage R1 for given daily predation rates and initial yield potentials in Figures 2.1-2.3. Figures 2.1a, 2.2a, and 2.3a correspond to results associated with a lower initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac, whereas Figures 2. l b, 2.2b, and 2.3b correspond to results for a higher initial yield potential of 60 bu/ac. The figures are not normal phase planes in the sense that the x-axis represents all possible values of S], y-axis represents all possible values of NE 1, and each x-y coordinate in the optimal control space corresponds to an 58 optimal control path (not just a control action at a decision point) determinedjointly by S, and NE 1. For instance, at a daily predation rate of 3S aphids/NE and an initial yield potential (ED/1]) of 60 bu/ac, the optimal control path is to control in both R1 and R2 and do nothing from R3 to R5 when S1=125 aphids/plant and NE1=0/plant (Figure 2.1b). We organize our presentation of the key results in the following five aspects: I ) Optimal control paths A total of three distinct optimal control paths emerge given the parameters used: (i) no control in all stages (“No spray”), (ii) control in stage R1 only (“Spray RI”), and iii) control in both R1 and R2 (“Spray R1+R2”). Note that since we have incorporated the population dynamics of natural enemies, any control action prescribed by the model remains optimal in spite of the opportunity cost of injury to natural enemies. While it is obvious that no insecticide spray is necessary during the last stage (R5), stages R3 and R4 are found to be too late to take any control action in any circumstances with respect to the values of S1 and NE 1. “No spray” and “Spray RI” strategies prevail in all circumstances, whereas “Spray R1+R2” has to be justified by relatively heavy infestation, low natural enemy population (or low predation rate), and high initial yield potential. Figures 2.1-2.3 show that, in the absence of natural suppression (i.e., NE 1=0), “Spray R1+R2” is never optimal when Ejyl] is as low as 40 bu/ac but becomes desirable in more heavily infested situations (512125) at a higher initial yield potential such as 60 bu/ac. Our results show that for a pest that is capable of rapid reproduction like SBA, early treatment actions are preferred over late actions, which is consistent with the current extension recommendation for managing SBA (NCPMC, 2005). The simulation model 59 finds that spraying twice in both R1 and R2 is the optimal control path for initial pest density exceeding 120 aphids/plant with no natural enemies present, whereas farmers and field entomologists wait longer between sprays. As Zhang (Essay 1) points out, the actual presence of natural enemies in the field, which reduces the need for insecticide control, along with two limitations of the model (i.e., omitting the residual effect of insecticides and the emigration of winged aphids) may have potentially contributed to the result. 2) The eflect of natural enemies on optimal control threshold In the absence of natural enemies as shown in the bottom rows of Figures 2.1-2.3, chemical control is cost-effective for initial pest density as low as 5 aphids/plant. This zero-natural enemy scenario exemplifies the assumption by many soybean farmers who ignore natural control services. Empirical observation shows that producers often do not hesitate to spray the fields, because of the relatively low cost of spray. The 3 aphids/plant action threshold suggested by Olson and Badibanga (2005) (the pest density at which action should be initiated to ensure spray is carried out by the 7th day from the observation of the density) is largely consistent with our result of treating SBA at 5 aphids/plant threshold only if the population of natural enemies is zeros. As Figure 2.1 shows, with just one natural enemy per plant, the optimal threshold is sharply increased to 30 aphids/plant—IO times of the level suggested by Olson and Badibanga (2005). Spraying a second time in R2 after the first treatment (i.e., optimal control path “Spray R1+R2”) would not be needed except when high pest pressure accompanies little 5 Among the four potential SBA treatment thresholds (3, 100, 250, and 500 aphids per plant) included in Olson and Badibanga (2005)’s analysis, 3 aphids/plant is the lowest threshold considered. It is expected that their model may suggest even smaller threshold if such scenario is included. 60 presence of natural enemies. For instance, at daily predation rate of 35 aphids/NE and initial yield potential of 60 bu/ac, the fields need to be sprayed twice in both R1 and R2 stages when initial infestation level is 125 aphids/plant and when there are no natural enemies (Figure 2.1b). The same SBA population density only needs one spray in R1 if natural enemy is just l/plant (Figure 2.1b). Although this finding is specific to the current model parameters, it demonstrates that wise insecticide strategy can conserve natural enemies, allowing them continue suppressing pest populations and avoiding excessive use of insecticides. 3) Eflect of variation in predation rate Predation rate plays an important role in determining the optimal control decisions. The effect is best illustrated by the shrinkage of the region for optimal control path “Spray R1” (or equivalently, the expansion of the region for “No spray”) in Figures 2.1-2.3 as the daily predation rate changes from 17 aphids/NE to the mean and maximum levels of 35 and 53 aphids/NE/day, respectively. A higher daily predation rate increases the threshold for insecticide use, implying that i) the same natural enemy density can now sustain a higher control threshold, or ii) fewer natural enemies are needed to sustain a given threshold density. For instance, Figure 2.2a suggests an optimal control threshold of 15 aphids/plant at NE 1=1/plant when daily predation rate is 17 aphids/NE, whereas the threshold becomes 30 and 45 aphids/plant for daily predation rate of 35 and 52 aphids/NE, respectively, holding the same initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac (Figures 2.1a and 2.3a). Predation rate is not a variable under farmer control. However, populations of species 61 that are particularly effective suppressing SBA may be targeted to improve predation rate through habitat management that provides compatible conditions favoring certain species. 4) Effect of variation in initial yield potential (or equivalently, historical yield level) The effect of initial yield potential on the choice of optimal control path is not obvious for moderately infested fields, i.e., Sl<125 aphids/plant. Provided that on average over 125 aphids per plant are scouted in stage R1, the same population densities of SBA and natural enemies may require more insecticides being used (i.e., optimal control path changes from “Spray R1” to “Spray R1+R2”) for fields with high initial yield potentials. “Spray R1+R2” would never be needed when the initial yield potential is at the low end of 40 bu/ac, regardless of the daily predation rate (Figures 2.1 to 2.3). The result conforms to the general expectation that more productive fields justify more insecticide use than the less productive ones at given output price and control cost. 5) Values of returns to producers over variable costs of control We plot the values of return over variable costs of control against initial SBA densities for two levels of initial natural enemy density in Figure 2.4. The initial yield potential is set at 40 bu/ac and the daily predation rate is 35 aphids/NE. The first curve (from the left) is associated with NE 1=0/plant, whereas the second one is associated with NE 1=l/plant. For NE 1=0, the return to producers from optimal SBA management over variable costs of control is a monotonically decreasing function of initial pest density (Figure 2.4). Starting at the maximum level of $276/ac when pest density equals zero (S,=0), the values of return steadily decline to $254/ac at the maximum SBA density level of 62 ISO/plant (corresponding to optimal control paths depicted in Figure 2.1a). For NE ,=1 , the predicted values of return show a plateau at the $276/ac level for S, between 0 and 25 aphids/plant, drop to $264/ac at S,=30/plant, and maintain the declining trend throughout the rest range of S ,. At a daily predation rate of 35 aphids/NE and initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac, as a field becomes more infested, the capability of a given level of natural enemies to maintain the maximum achievable return of $276/ac declines, although higher NE, naturally leads to larger return for given initial SBA density as compared to lower NE ,. At a higher daily predation rate such as 52 aphids/NE, however, an initial density of 4 natural enemies per plant is able to maintain the maximum achievable return ($276/ac), even in the most SBA infested fields (not shown in the figure). 6) Economic value of natural pest control services These numerical results can be used to make a preliminary estimate of the value of the natural pest control ecosystem service. The value is calculated from the increase in return to producers over variable costs of control as a result of an increased initial population of natural enemies so the estimate constitutes a lower bound for the total economic value of this ecosystem service because it omits such benefits as the avoidance of health and environmental risks from insecticide spraying. The value is context-dependent, because the marginal value of an additional unit of natural enemy population not only depends on the predation rate, initial yield potential and pest population, but also the existing natural enemy population and prices. To illustrate, we plot in Figure 2.5 values of an initial natural enemy density of l per plant as compared to the baseline of zero natural enemies per plant for various initial pest 63 densities for an initial yield potential-daily predation rate scenario defined in Figure 2.4. At a daily predation rate of 35 aphids/NE and initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac, the presence of one natural enemy per plant in R1 (as compared to none) implies a sequence of minimum values associated with given initial pest populations: for instance, $12.50/ac at S,= 5/plant (corresponding to optimal control path changing from “Spray Rl” to “No spray” in Figure 2.13), and $13.90/ac at S,= 25/plant (corresponding to optimal control path changing form “Spray Rl” to “No spray” in Figure 2.1a), from where the value declines as S, increases. That the value at S,= 25/plant is higher than that at S,= 5/plant is because higher SBA density is capable of causing more yield loss. Figure 2.5 also indicates that there is always a positive gain in return to producers (at the minimum $1 .70/ac when S,=150 aphids/plant and initial yield potential is 40 bu/ac) due to the presence of one natural enemy per plant as compared to the NE ,=0 baseline, so long as the field is infested with SBA (i.e., S,>0). The minimum gain is lower, at $0.03/ac when S,=150 aphids/plant, if the initial yield potential is increased from 40 bu/ac to 60 bu/ac (not shown in the figure), implying a relative advantage of using natural enemies to control pests on less productive land. When existing natural enemies are already at a relatively high density, such as 3/plant, one more natural enemy does not convey any economic value unless the field is infested with more than 75 aphids/plant in R1. Aggregating these results for the value of natural enemies for the broad region is difficult. The reason is that we cannot observe the correct area where insecticide treatment could have been averted because natural enemies adequately suppressed SBA numbers. The problem is that in the real world we do not observe the counterfactual cases 64 of (3) acres that never reached threshold because of natural enemies, and (b) acres that were treated but did not need it because natural enemies would have contained SBA damage. 2.5 Sensitivity analysis To assess the effect of uncertainty associated with the economic and biological parameters used in the dynamic optimization analysis, we perform a sensitivity analysis on selected, key parameters by changing parameters one at a time holding the rest constant and comparing the results with the baseline which is based on parameters reported in Table 2.1. For a case in which daily predation rate is 35 aphids/NE and initial yield potential is 40 bu/ac, a total of 18 scenarios are examined (Table 2.2). Parameters estimated from field data are increased and/or decreased by one standard deviation, whereas parameters that are assumed or derived from other studies are increased and/or decreased by 5%, respectively, except for the two economic parameters, output price and control cost, whose values are varied by 20% and 50%, respectively". Table 2.2 summarizes the major results from the sensitivity analysis. Specifically, we look at two aspects of changes from baseline resulted from varying parameters: choice of optimal control path and values of return over variable costs of control. 1) Choice of optimal control path Varying the values of most of the parameters does not alter the selection of optimal control paths in most scenarios with the exception of reducing the mortality rate of SBA 6 We also ran scenarios for 5% of change in the values of output price and control cost and found no impact on the model results when varying control cost and only 5% of gain (or loss) when price is increased (or decreased) by 5%. 65 to insecticide (k5,) by 5% and varying control cost by 50% (Table 2.2). Lower insecticide efficacy rate means that SBA population is more likely to rapidly rebound after spraying so that delaying spray when there is reasonable amount of natural enemies present can become attractive. As a result, at a daily predation rate of 35 aphids/NE and initial yield potential of 40 bu/ac, a 5% decrease in kg, leads to the selection of optimal control path “Spray R2” over “Spray Rl” when low-medium SBA population (30-70 aphids/plant) is combined with relatively abundant natural enemies (1-2 NE/plant). On the one hand, too low of a SBA population (below 30 aphids/plant) does notjustify any spray unless no natural enemies are present. On the other hand, given low-medium SBA population, “Spray R1+R2” would be preferred over “Spray Rl” if natural enemy population is relatively low (no greater than 2 NE/plant) or no spray would be needed otherwise (i.e., higher than 2 NE/plant). When SBA population is relatively high (between 70 and 110 aphids/plant), however, 5% reduction in kg, results in the choice of “Spray R1+R2” over “Spray RI”, unless the natural enemy population is high enough to warrant “No spray”. For SBA population above 110 aphids/plant, spray twice in both R1 and R2 would be needed, regardless of natural enemy population. The analysis also shows that a 5% increase in the survival rate of natural enemies is not large enough to induce any change to the choice of optimal control path, given the daily predation rate and initial yield potential considered in this case. Given the low initial yield potential (40 bu/ac) considered in the current analysis, 20% change in soybean price does not have a significant impact on the choice of optimal control path (Table 2.2). Varying control cost by 50% does result in limited changes from the baseline. Specifically, increasing control cost by 50% only slightly scales down the 66 incentive for spraying in RI as opposed to “No spray” at medium SBA population, reconfirming the relative cost-effectiveness of current practice of insecticide application, especially when natural enemies are less than abundant in the field. This finding is reinforced by the scenario of reducing control cost by 50%, which calls for more frequent sprays (i.e., “Spray R1+R2” over “Spray R1”) for relatively high SBA population when there is limited presence of natural enemies. 2) Values of return over variable costs of control While varying the output price by 20% does not affect the choice of optimal control path, output price variation has the greatest impact on producer’s return over variable costs of control, followed by scenarios reducing the mortality rate of SBA to insecticide by 5%. Specifically, varying output price by 20% leads to roughly proportional change in the value of return. Reducing the mortality rate of SBA to insecticide by 5% results in losses in return ranging from 2 to 5%, with impacts rising with SBA density. Reducing the mortality rate of natural enemies to insecticide by 5% slightly improves the returns over variable costs by up to 2.5%. Varying control cost by 50% has disproportionately small financial effects in terms of change in return over variable costs of control (ranging from 0 to 4%). This result demonstrates again the high payoff to insecticide application even for land with initial yield potential as low as 40 bu/ac. In the two price sensitivity scenarios, the impact on model results grows as initial pest population rises, while the initial natural enemy level tends to muffle the effects. In the two insect mortality rate scenarios, impact also grows as initial pest population rises but relatively low (or high) natural enemy populations accompanying a relatively low (or 67 high) SBA population are responsible for greater effects. The remaining sensitivity analysis scenarios have negligible impacts on returns above central costs. 2.6 Conclusion The control of pests by their natural enemies represents an important ecosystem service that has the potential to mitigate pest control costs both to private producers and to society. This important ecosystem service, as well as the unintended effect of broad- spectrum insecticides on the populations of natural enemies, however, have not been included in the existing economic models of optimal pest management (e.g., Talpaz and Borosh, 1974; Zacharias and Grube, 1986; Harper et al., 1994; Bor, 1995), nor has any applicable decision guide been offered to crop farmers to conserve and capitalize on the pest regulation services supplied by ambient natural enemies. The current North Central states extension recommendation of action threshold of 250 aphids per plant given a 7-day window between the observation of the pest density and actual insecticide application (Ragsdale et al., 2007) has been introduced as an Integrated Pest Management alternative to prophylactic SBA control. The recommendation is based on a static approach that does not account for the dynamic effects of insecticide application on natural enemies and consequently the population of the pest, especially when multiple treatments are needed. Moreover, the recommendation does not provide specific guidance on the timing of applying this threshold nor does it offer any applicable guide on how to incorporate natural enemies into pest management decision-making. Olson and Badibanga (2005)’s model implies that even the smallest population density of SBA can justify insecticide treatment, regardless of aphid growth 68 rate. Their conclusion is only consistent with findings from this study in the absence of natural enemies. Using a simulation experiment developed for the soybean aphid and ladybeetle prey-predator system, this study examines the difference in optimal control actions chosen with and without the consideration of natural enemies and how that difference is translated into economic gain. The results highlight the importance of assessing both pest and natural enemy populations in making pest management decisions and accounting for the opportunity cost of insecticide collateral damage to natural enemies. However, it is important to recognize that the current model is limited by some simplifications. For instance, the absence of the insecticide residual effect and insect migration behavior from the model can potentially lead to overestimation of the urgency and frequency of sprays, which has likely contributed to the lower control threshold suggested by the model than the extension recommendation, regardless of our account of the natural enemy levels. With the further incorporation of practical issues such as stochastic environmental and weather factors, time lag needed by farmers to prepare for insecticide application after the control decision is made, and the development of applicable measures of natural enemy population density, the current simple framework can potentially be developed into a decision aid model. Based on the results from the dynamic optimization analysis, this study provides preliminary estimates of the economic value of natural pest control ecosystem service in the management of soybean aphid. These values reflect the economic benefit from an increase in the natural enemy population as inferred from the output value of the marketed soybean product, given that control decisions already take into account natural 69 pest control services (i.e., decisions that are optimal in spite of the opportunity cost of injury to natural enemies by broad-spectrum insecticides). While caution should be paid to the extrapolation of the estimated values due to their context dependence, they offer instrumental insights on the magnitude of the economic value of natural enemy population management to private producers. In the long run, effective agroecosystem management will demand more of managers than simply to reduce the non-target effect of pesticides on natural enemies. Habitat management that improves landscape complexity can potentially benefit natural enemies and in most cases result in enhanced biological control of pests (Thies and Tschamtke, 1999; Wilby and Thomas, 2002; Cardinale et al., 2003; Ostman et al., 2003; Thies et al., 2003). Future research should move beyond insecticide use thresholds to develop landscape-scale guidelines for explicit management of habitat for the natural enemies of agricultural pests. 70 References Alleman, R.J., C.R. Grau, and DB. Hogg. 2002. “Soybean aphid host range and virus transmission efficiency.” Paper presented at Wisconsin Fertilizer, Aglime, and Pest Management Conference, Madison WI. http://www.soils.wisc.edu/ nextension/FAPM/ fertaglime02.htm Aponte, W., and D. Calvin. 2004. “Entomological notes: soybean aphid.” Department of Entomology, Pennsylvania State University. http://www.ento.psu.edu/extension/ factsheets/soybeanAphid.htm Barbosa, P., and S. Braxton. 1993. “A proposed definition of biological control and its relationship to related control approaches.” In R.D. Lumsden and J.L. Vaughn, ed. Pest Management: Biologically Based Technologies(Proceedings of Beltsville Symposium XVIII, Agricultural Research Services, USDA. Beltsville MD, 2-6 May, 1993). Washington, DC: American Chemical Society. Berg, H. van den, D. Ankasah, A. Muhammad, R. Rusli, H.A. Widayanto, H.B. Wirasto, and I. Yully. 1997. “Evaluating the role of predation in population fluctuations of the soybean aphid Aphis glycines in farmers’ field in Indonesia.” Journal of Applied Ecology 34(4): 971-984. Calkins, CO. 1983. “Research on exotic pests.” In C.L. Wilson and C.L. Graham, ed. Exotic Plant Pests and North American Agriculture. New York: Academic Press, pp. 321-359. Cardinale, B.J., C.T. Harvey, K. Gross, A.R. Ives. 2003. “Biodiversity and biocontrol: emergent impacts of a multi-enemy assemblage on pest suppression and crop yield in an agroecosystem.” Ecology Letters 6: 857-65. Costamagna, A.C. 2006. “Do varying natural enemy assemblages impact Aphis glycines population dynamics?” PhD Dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Costamagna, A.C., and DA. Landis. 2006. “Predators exert top-down control of soybean aphid across a gradient of agricultural management systems.” Ecological Applications 16(4): 161 9-1 628. Costamagna, A.C., D.A. Landis, and CD. DiFonzo. 2007. “Suppression of soybean aphid by generalist predators results in a trophic cascade in soybeans.” Ecological Applications 17(2):441—451 . DiFonzo, CD, and R. Hines. 2002. “Soybean aphid in Michigan: update from the 2001. season.” Michigan State University Extension Bulletin E-2748, East Lansing, MI. 71 Fang, H.S., H.H. Nee, and T.G. Chou. 1985. “Comparative ability of seventeen aphid species to transmit tobacco vein-banding mosaic virus.” Bulletin of Taiwan Tobacco Research Institute 22: 41-46. F enemore, PG. 1982. Plant Pests and Their Control. Wellington, New Zealand: Butterworths. Fox, T.B., D.A. Landis, F .F. Cardoso, and CD. Difonzo. 2004. “Predators Suppress Aphis glycines Matsumura Population Growth in Soybean.” Environmental Entomology 33(3): 608-618. Harper, J.K., J .W. Mjelde, M.E. Rister, M.O. Way, and BM. Drees. 1994. “Developing flexible economic thresholds for pest management using dynamic programming.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 26(1): 134-147. Headley, J .C. 1972. “Defining the economic threshold.” In Pest Control Strategies for the Future. Washington DC: National Academy of Sciences, pp. 100-108. Hill, G., and D. Greathead. 2000. “Economic evaluation in classical biological control.” In C. Perrings, M.H. Williamson, and S. Dalmazzone, ed. The Economics of Biological Invasions. Northampton MA: Edward Elgar: pp. 208-226. Jameson-Jones, S. 2005. “Insect and insect management: soybean aphid.” University of Minnesota Extension. by;://www.soybeans.umn.edu/crg)/insects/aphid/gajgghid. ht_m. Accessed May 25, 2005. Kaiser, M.E., T. Noma, M.J. Brewer, K.S. Pike, J.R. Vockeroth, and SD. Gaimari. 2007. “Hymenopteran parasitoids and dipteran predators found using soybean aphid after its midwestem United States invasion.” Annals of the Entomological Society of America 100(2): 196-205. Krishna, V.V., N.G., Byju, and S., Tamizheniyan. 2003. “Integrated pest management in Indian agriculture: a developing economic perspective.” In E.B. Radcliff and W.D. Hutchson, ed. [PM World Textbook. St. Paul MN: University of Minnesota. Landis, D.A., T.B. Fox, and A.C. Costamagna. 2004. “Impact of multicolored Asian Lady Beetle as a biological control agent.” American Entomologist 50(3): 1 53-1 54. Losey, J.E., and M. Vaughan. 2006. “The economic value of ecological services provided by insects.” Bioscience 56(4): 331-323. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MA). 2005. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press. 72 Miranda, M.J., and PL. Fackler. 2002. “CompEcon Toolbox for MatLab.” MatLab library functions developed to accompany M.J. Miranda and PL. F ackler. 2002. Applied Computational Economics and Finance. Cambridge MA: MIT Press. httg//www4.ncsu.edu/~pfackler/cormaecon/toolbox.html MSU Field Crops AOE Team. 2002. “Determining Best Management Practices for control of the soybean aphid in Michigan.” Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. http://fieldcropmsu.edu/documents/02039%20Controlling% 2OSoybean%20 aphidpdf Musser, F.R., J .P. Nyrop, and A.M. Shelton.2006. “Integrating biological and chemical controls in decision making: European corn borer (Lepidoptera: Crambidae) control in sweet corn as an example.” Journal of Economic Entomology 99(5): 1538-1549. National Soybean Research Laboratory (N SRL). 2002. “Illinois soybean pathology and entomology research: soybean aphid.” University of Illinois NSRL Factsheet #4. http://www.nsrl.uiuc.edu/. National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS). 2007. “Agricultural Chemical Usage Database.” US. Department of Agriculture. mzflwwwpestmanagement.info/ nass/ Naylor, R., and P. Ehrlich. 1997. “Natural pest control services and agriculture.” In G. Daily, ed. Nature ’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Washington DC: Island Press, pp. 151-74. Nielsen, C., and A.E., Hajek. 2005. “Control of invasive soybean aphid, Aphis glycines (Hemiptera: Aphididae), population by existing natural enemies in New York State, with emphasis on entomophathogenic fungi.” Environmental Entomology 34(5): 1036-1047. North Central Pest Management Center (N CPMC). 2005. “National pest alert: soybean aphid.” US. Department of Agriculture. http://www.ncpmc.org/alerts/soybcan aphidcfm Olson, K., and T. Badibanga. 2005. “A bioeconomic model of the soybean aphid treatment decision in soybeans.” Paper presented at American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Providence RI, 24-27 July. http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgi-bin/pdf_view.pl?paperid= l 6358&fivpe=.pdf O’Neal, M. 2007. “Practices to conserve and use natural enemies in soybean aphid 1PM. Managing soybean aphids in 2007: how will biological control contribute?” Distance education short course, North Central Soybean Research Program, March 6, 2007. 73 Ostman, O., B. Ekbom, and J. Bengtsson. 2003. “Yield increase attributable to aphid predation by ground-living polyphagous natural enemies in spring barley in Sweden.” Ecological Economics 45: 149-58. Pedigo, L.P., S.H. Hutchins, and LG. Higley. 1986. “Economic injury levels in theory and practice.” Annual Review of Entomology 31: 341-68. Pimentel, D., C. Wilson, C. McCullum, R. Huang, P. Dwen, J. Flack, Q. Tran, T. Saltman, and B. Cliff. 1997. “Economic and environmental benefits of biodiversity.” BioScience 47(1 1): 47-757. Ragsdale, D.W., B.P. McComack, R.C. Venette, B.D. Potter, I.V. MacRae, E.W. Hodgson, M.E. O’Neal, K.D. Johnson, R.J. O’Neil, C.D. DiFonzo, T.E. Hunt, P.A. Glogoza, and E. M. Cullen. 2007. “Economic threshold for soybean aphid (Hemiptera: Aphididae).” Journal of Economic Entomology 100(4): 1258-1267. Risk Avoidance and Mitigation Program project on “Soybean Aphid in the North Central US: Implementing 1PM at the Landscape Scale” (RAMP). 2006. Project Update Vol. 2-2 (June). http://www.soybeans.umn.edu/crop/insects/aphid/aphid_ramg ht_m Rutledge, C.E., R.J. O'Neil, T.B. Fox, and D.A. Landis. 2004. “Soybean aphid predators and their use in 1PM.” Annals of the Entomological Society of America 97:240- 248. Smith, GS, and D. Pike. 2002. “Soybean pest management strategic plan.” US. Department of Agriculture North Central Region Pest Management Center and United Soybean Board. Song, F., S.M. Swinton, C. DiFonzo, M. O'Neal, and D.W. Ragsdale. 2006. “Profitability analysis of soybean aphid control treatments in three north-central states.” Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper No. 2006-24, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgibin/pdf_view.pl? pgperid=23574&ftype =.pdf Stevenson, W.R., and OR. Grau. 2003. “Virus resistance: a possible solution to snap bean loss.” Paper presented at Wisconsin Fertilizer, Aglime, and Pest Management Conference, Madison WI. http://www.soils.wisc.edu/nextension/ FAPM/ fertaglime02.htm Swinton, S.M., and W. Zhang. 2005. “Rethinking ecosystem services from an intermediate product perspective.” Paper presented at American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Providence RI, 24-27 July. http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgi-bin/pdf_view.pl?_paperid=l 6238&ftype=.pdf 74 Tammes, P.M.L. 1961. “Studies of yield losses. II. Injury as a limiting factor of yield.” Tijdschr. Plantenziekten 67: 257-63. Thies, C., and T. Tschamtke. 1999. “Landscape structure and biological control in agroecosystems.” Science 285(5429): 893-895. Thies, C., I. Steffan-Dewenter, and T. Tschamtke. 2003. “Effects of landscape context on herbivory and parasitism at different spatial scales.” Oikos 101: 18-25. Thomas, MB. 1999. “Ecological approaches and the development of ‘truly integrated’ pest management.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 96(May): 5944-5951 . Thompson, A., and T. German. 2003. “Soybean aphid and virus incidence in snap beans.” Paper presented at Wisconsin Fertilizer, Aglime, and Pest Management Conference, Madison, WI. http://www.soils.wisc.edu/nextension/FAPM/ fertaglime02.htm Wilby, A., and MB. Thomas. 2002. “Natural enemy diversity and pest control: patterns of pest emergence with agricultural intensification.” Ecology Letters 5: 353-60. Zacharias, TR, and AH. Grube. 1986. “Integrated Pest Management strategies for approximately optimal control of corn rootworm and soybean cyst nematode.” American Journal of A gricultural Economics 68(3): 704-715. Zhang, W. Essay 1. “Bioeconomic modeling for natural enemy-adjusted economic threshold: an application to soybean aphid.” PhD dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. 75 Table 2.1: Values of parameters from Zhang (Essay Q’s model Parameters R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 Duration of plant growth stage (day) 3 10 9 9 IS Mortality rate of SBA from insecticides (k5,) 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Mortality rate of natural enemies from insecticides (kNm) 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 0.99 Natural enemies Net decline rate of NE (61,) -0.59 -0.90*** -2.13** Reproduction rate of NE per prey encountered (b,) 0.002 -0.0001 0002* Soybean aphid Net growth rate of SBA population (ng,) 5.29 5.15 2.35 1.13 Predation rate per natural enemy per stage (Prr) daily predation rate=l7/NE 51 170 153 153 daily predation rate=35/NE 105 350 315 315 daily predation rate=52/NE 156 520 468 468 Soybean yield Proportion of yield lost per unit of pest population (’lt) 0.0002 -0.001** 0.0003* 0.0001* 0.0002 Maximum proportional yield loss to pest damage (19,) 1 1 1 1 1 Economic parameters Output price (p) $6.9/bu Control cost (c(x,)) $12.2/ac * significant at 90%; ** significant at 95%; *** significant at 99%. Source: Zhang (Essay 1) 76 Table 2.2: Summary of sensitivity analysis results organized by ranges of initial SBA densities (Initial yield potential=40 bu/ac, daily predation rate=35 aphids/NE) Changs from baseline model results' Returns to producers over variable Scenarios Optimal control paths costs of control 2055,540 40 0 ). Under HM, the farmer is assumed to rely on NCH for pest management. For the ease of exposition, we assume natural pest control services are evenly distributed to each point within a radius of r, meaning that each cell within the “impact zone” enjoys the same amount of pest reduction. The total net return under HM (NRNCH) is expressed as the sum of net retums from NCH cells, crop cells within the impact zone, and crop cells outside the impact zone: ' For an organic farm, cache", =0, c=0. 89 NRNCH = 0 - Am, + IZ-tpy°<1— DNCH)- VC(1+ 4)1+ NIZ-[pyOU - Do) - VC(1+ 4)] (6) where DNCH = D[(1— (UNCH )IO] = D0 + ADNCH , IZ denotes the area of the “impact zone” (i.e., the number of cells within radius r), NIZ (“no-impact zone”) denotes the area of the crop fields that receives no impact, and ADM.” represents the decline in the proportion of yield damage due to NCH. Substituting equation (4) into (6) and rearranging terms, we can rewrite (6) as: NRNCH = NM-no — ANCH x0 —,1- VC(NM — ANCH)+ IZ - pyOADNCH (7) The RHS of equation (7) indicates two sources of cost due to designating ANCH cells of land as habitats: i) forgone income from NCH cells (AMHrtO ), and ii) change in variable costs of production on all crop cells (zl- VC (NM — AM.” ) ). The last term represents a gain in the output value of the crop harvested in the impact zone. The distribution of the benefits and costs of the management approach shows a clear spatial distinction. Assuming there exists a non-trivial interior solution, the first-order condition (FOC) for the maximization of equation (7) with respect to A NCH is m=A-VC—VC- 8’1 (NM—ANCH)—fl0+pyO-IZ-aiD—&H— NCH aANCH aANCH (8) 0 BIZ +Py 'ADNCH ' aANCH = Rearranging terms of equation (8), we have py0[IZ'%—DM+ADNCH' aIZ 1:7[0-A'VC'I'VC' all BANCH aANCH ANCH (NM “Awe/1) (9) Equation (9) renders the classic optimal condition for the choice of land use type that balances the marginal factor cost (MFC) of setting aside an additional crop cell (the RHS 90 of the equation) with the marginal value product (MVP) of the action in terms of improved output value due to pest regulation (the LHS of the equation). The MFC includes the opportunity cost of potential net return from a crop cell (no — xl- VC) as well as a potential increase in variable costs by the amount of BA/BAMW that applies to all crop cells. In addition to condition (9), the following relationship has to hold in order for a HM approach to be economically preferable over insecticide control: NRNCH > NRchem. (10) Substituting equations (3) and (7) into (10), we derive IZ ' PyoADNCH > ANCH '”0 + 4' VC (NM — ANCH)+ NM '[PyOADchem ‘6] (1 I) The expression suggests that the size of the NCH element ANCH must be chosen in a way that the benefit of yield saving collected in the impact zone is greater than the sum of three terms: i) the opportunity cost of setting aside an area of ANCH for NCH purpose, ii) the increased production cost due to field fragmentation caused by NCH, and iii) the output value of the yield saving resulted from pesticide control less the cost of control aggregated over the entire crop field. The spatially explicit impacts of ANC,, on ecological factors such as [Z and ADM.” and economic factor variable costs change (2.) are not easy to show analytically using mathematical notations. However, generally speaking, 132/ BA m, >0 if longer machinery field time is needed to farm the fragmented field as a result of changing ANCH. While it is intuitive that ANCH tends to positively affect 12, its impact on ADM .H is somewhat mixed. In the current problem where there is only one NCH element and change in Axon only 91 affects the area of the element, BAD,“ /8A <0 is possible if i) a negative scale N('H dependence relationship presents between the density of pest control agents and the size of individual NCH element (Hambaeck and Englund, 2005), so that an increase in the size of NCH element may actually lead to lower pest control services, and ii) the increase in the area of impact zone due to change in Ave” is disproportionately higher than the increase in pest control services available as ANCH increases, so that on average each cell received less pest reduction impact. In cases where a unit of increase in ANCH is associated with the establishment of an additional NCH element, it is conceivable that the new element generates its own impact zone but .12 and ADM.” of existing elements are not affected so long as there is no overlap in impact zones and each NCH element is an independent source of ecological benefits. Finally, as more realistic distribution functions are adopted to describe the dispersal of pest control services into surrounding fields, ADM.” is expected to change nonlinearly with distance from the source of the services. While the current model looks at a simple static problem, it is worth noting that some economic aspects of non-temporary NCH are inherently dynamic. In a soybean- com rotation, for instance, the opportunity cost of setting aside land to provide pest control services for soybean carries on into the production of the rotating crop corn, making NCH more expensive, especially if corn production does not benefit from the NCH. 3.3 Empirical model First discovered in 2000, soybean aphid (Aphis glycines, Matsumura) is a new invasive pest of soybeans in the North Central region of the United States that is capable of 92 causing extensive damage to soybean yield (DiFonzo and Hines, 2002). Existing natural enemy communities, especially generalist predator ladybeetles (Coccinellidae) play a key role in suppressing soybean aphid populations (Costamagna et al., 2007a; Fox et al., 2004; Rutledge et al., 2004) and are believed to have contributed to the observed two- year cycle of aphid population where aphid outbreaks occur every two yearsz. The development of insights to enhance and capitalize on the pest control services supplied by ladybeetles through HM, therefore, is of interest not only to private producers but also to the general public with respect to protecting a major commodity crop without large scale spraying of chemical insecticide. Using the soybean aphid-ladybeetle example, we develop an empirical model that combines i) an ecological module for calculating the distribution of pest control services given the distribution of NCH in the landscape and a distribution kernel that represents the spatial probability distribution of pest control services around a source origin", and ii) an economic module for evaluating the net return to fixed factors of crop production, given a land use pattern (see MatLab code in Appendix B). The two models are coupled with an optimization method that finds the land use patterns that are most economically desirable among the patterns considered given parameters assumed. By focusing on selected patterns, we effectively delimit a relevant sub-space within the full optimization solution space. The approach is chosen over performing a global search over all possible land use patterns to find an optimal solution to the problem, whose computational cost can be exceedingly high (Polasky et al., 2005). 2 Douglas A. Landis, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University, personal communication, September 27, 2005. 3 Wopke van der Werf, Department of Plant Sciences, Wageningen University, personal communications, October 2006 to December 2006. Dr. van der Werf is also a contributor to the simulation model code. 93 To illustrate our approach we apply the model to a simple agricultural landscape composed of 1600 ha (4,000 m><4,000 m) square cells or land parcels, arranged in a 800 X 800 grid (n=800) with each cell being 25 m2 in size (Figures 3.2a to 3.20). For simplicity, we assume that there is no existing natural habitat in the landscape. The hypothetical landscape is arbitrarily divided into four square, homogenous full-time soybean-com farms each with the size of 400 ha (or about 988 acres)4, arranged in a 2X2 checkboard (Figures 3.2a to 3.2c). We assume the economic agents are rational and thus consider only a selected set of options regarding the shape and location of NCH elements. Specifically, since pest control services are dispersed around a source origin within a certain range, private producers would choose to place the NCH elements in the center of the farm so that the farm enjoys as much the services as possibles. For practical consideration, we eliminate irregularly shaped NCH elements and consider three shape options: squares, strips, and archipelago. In the square distribution (Figure 3.2a), there is a square ofs by s NCH cells in the centre of each farm. In the strip configuration (Figure 3.2b), a strip of width w (counted in cells) runs through the axis of each farm. Finally, a landscape is introduced with random allocation of cells to either NCH (with probability equal to the proportion of NCH in the landscape, denoted by prop_NCH) or crop (with probability l-prop_NCH). Figure 3.2c gives a result for prob_NCH = 0.1. The use of selected configuration options effectively simplifies the optimization problem, making it possible to focus the optimization on the area of NCH (or prob_NCH) and choice among three shapes of NCH elements. 4 According to a national survey, the typical sizes of small, mid-size, and large commercial farms in the United States are 160, 605 and 2180 acres, respectively (USDA, 2000). 5 In the current analysis, we don’t consider the spillover of NCH benefits. 94 Ecological module for the distribution of pest control services Relationships between a parameter or a variable and spatial scale are often called scale dependencies (Hambaeck and Englund, 2005). Empirical research has shown that animal densities may both increase and decrease with habitat patch size (Hambaeck and Englund, 2005), a scale dependence effect that may conceivably apply to the relationship between the pest control impact of insect natural enemies and the size of individual habitat patches (i.e., NCH elements). The resource concentration hypothesis (Root, 1973) predicts that specialist herbivores should achieve higher densities in large patches. Hambaeck and Englund (2005) propose a power relationship to model theoretical scaling relationships and use the model predictions to explain variability in density-area relations from published studies on herbivorous insect-dominated systems. However, quantitative measures of the relationship between insect predator density (and consequently the services they provide) and habitat size are not available. In the following numerical analysis, we assume predator density (or the services provided) does not depend on the size of NCH element (i.e., no scale dependence). We discuss implications of a positive relationship for pest management in the last section of the paper6. Assuming there is one unit of the density of pest control services (“impact”) for each area unit of NCH, the amount of services per NCH cell is proportional to the area of a cell and the amount of services in an NCH element is proportional to the area of the element. Specifically, Services per NCH element = (Density of pest control services) * (Area of NC H element) 6 Given the absence of scale dependence and the homogeneous farm assumptions, solving the landscape problem is essentially the same as solving four individual farm problems and then aggregating them for the entire landscape. We keep the multiple-farrn landscape model rather than focusing on farrn-level problem to allow for future exploration of landscape-scale coordination possibilities. 95 The services stored in each NCH element are dispersed into surrounding crop area according to a distribution kernel, which describes the probability distribution of landing locations of services around the source origin in a two-dimensional plane (Skelsey et al., 2005). The positions x and y are distances from the source, and K(x,y) is the probability density at location (xy) (Skelsey et al., 2005). We consider 3 options of distribution kernels (Figures 3.3a to 3.3c): i) vertical cylinder (Figure 3.3a) with a probability density equal to MIT) within a radius r from the source, and 0 elsewhere War2 for (Ix2+y2 5r 0 for (Ix2+y2 >r ii) rotated exponential (Laplace) kernel (Figure 3.3b) 2 K(x.y)=“— _a,.2.,2 (13) e 27: K(x,y)= (12) where a is the slope of the decline of allocated services with distance, and iii) two- dimensional normal (Gaussian) kernel (Figure 3.3c) _:2+_yz 1 202 K(x.y)= , e (14) 27r6 where 6 represents the standard deviation. The mean dispersal distance in the plane is r for a cylindrical kernel, 2/01 for a Laplace kernel, and 6H for a Gaussian kernel. The Laplace kernel has a stronger peak and more rapid decay as compared to the Gaussian kernel, whereas the cylindrical kernel has a flat top near the center rather than a sharp peak. The Laplace kernel has been used in the ecological literature to model the dispersal of ladybeetles (e.g., Bianchi and van der Werf, 2003; Bianchi et al., 2007). The other two 96 kernels are included in order to investigate the sensitivity of model outcomes to differently shaped kernels. Allocated actual control impact measured in terms of the percentage of reduction in pest density per unit area of crop area is proportional to the “impact” per unit area of NCH and depends on the proportion of NCH in the landscape which corresponds to an overall pest reduction magnitude across crop fields. We estimate the relationship between the average percentage of reduction in pest density across crop fields and the proportion of NCH in the landscape using simulation results from Bianchi and van der Werf (2003) (Appendix C) for the interaction between aphids in wheat and Coccinella septempunctata, a major aphid predator in the ladybeetle family that has been identified as a major contributor to the natural suppression of soybean aphids (McKeown, 2003; Costamagna, 2006) (Figure 3.4)7. Although the scale of the landscape simulated in Bianchi and van der Werf (2003) is smaller than the one defined in our model, which may potentially lead to over-estimation of the pest control impact of NCH, their model provides the best available quantitative information on the relationship between aphid density and the proportion of NCH in the landscape as a result of C occinella septempunctata predation. Other potential sources of secondary data, including the empirical studies by Thies and Tschamtke (I 999) and Thies et al. (2003) are not suitable because they look at the parasitoid category of natural enemies, which is likely to have different pest-natural enemy interaction and require different resources from habitats as compared to predators. Figures 3.5(i)a to 3.5(i)c, 3.5(ii)a to 3.5(ii)c, and 3.5(iii)a to 3.5(iii)c render graphical 7 To find values at intermediate points, we use the “interpl” command in MatLab that performs linear interpolation between data points (The MathWorks Inc., 1994-2007). 97 illustrations of the distribution of pest control services from various shapes of NCH, given 10% of landscape area devoted to NCH. Economic module for the evaluation of land use decisions Practice of pest management varies with farming systems, which has important implications for the economic performance of HM on private producers. We consider two types of farming systems, a conventional system and an organic systems. In the baseline, we assume that the application of chemical insecticides is triggered by the occurrence of the new soybean pest in a conventional farm, whereas synthetic insecticides are not allowed in an organic farm so that the pest goes untreated9. Under HM, both farming systems rely on NCH to control soybean aphid. We define net returns to fixed factors (NR) for a soybean-com rotation (one crop at a time) as following: Baseline: NRbase = NRbase__ soy + NRbase_ com (15) HM: NRNCH = NRNCH _ soy + NRNCH _corn (16) where NRbase _soy = [Psoy 'ybase_ soy - VC soy — T C051 sprayI' Areatotal (17) gives the baseline net return for soybean, which is derived by multiplying the total land area (represented by total number of cells), Area,,,,,,,, by the net return per cell. p5,,y is the price of soybean output ($/ton), VC,,,y denotes variable costs of production, and TC ostspmy 8 To ensure a healthy system, certified organic farms are often required to include one and sometimes two other crops rotated with soybean and corn (Delate, 2003). Our loosely defined organic farm, however, only includes two rotating crops, soybean and com. This simplification makes direct comparison between conventional and organic systems easier without affecting the implications we draw from the analysis. 9 Many organic farms use non-synthetic insecticides such as biological insecticides, but usually on higher value crops than soybean and com. 98 represents the cost of soybean aphid control (T Cost,,,,,,y=Costspmy *Number__of_sprays). Both VC,,,, and T Costspmy are scaled to a per-cell base ($/cell). The baseline yield (ton/cell), ybasejoy is described by a Cousens hyperbolic yield function (Cousens, 1985): 77 [(1 _ Eflicacy spray )p es’initial I ] (1 8) ybase_ soy = y 50)“ _ max I — 1 + n[(l - Eflicacyspmy )PeStinitial I / r“ where ysoyJw is the maximum (pest-free) yield potential, Eflicacy,,,,,,y is the efficacy rate of soybean aphid insecticides, pest,,,,,,,,, is the untreated average pest density, n denotes the proportion of yield lost per unit of pest population, and ,1 denotes the maximum proportional yield loss to pest damage (05 ,u 51). Assuming equal efficacy rate across crop cells, ybase_,0y is a scalar. Similarly, the baseline net return for corn is given by: N Rbase _corn = Ipcorn 'ybase_ corn " VCcorn] ' Ar eatotal (1 9) The net return for soybean under HM is: Areasoy NRNCH _ soy = E [Hwy 'yNCH _ soy,l — (l + 4): V C soy] (20) where 2, determined by NCH configuration, measures the average change in variable costs of production per crop cell due to change in field configuration caused by NCH, and AreaNCH denotes the area of NCH (represented by the number of NCH cells). The summation operator is necessary because the amount of pest control services allocated to each crop cell (and consequently crop yield) is spatially variant rather than uniform across crop cells as in equation (18). Soybean yield in crop cell 1 (ton/cell), yN(7H_soy.r, thus is described by the Cousens hyperbolic yield function (Cousens, I985): _ nrtl—anpestim-aal ) (21) 1 + 77[(1 - at )pestmmar 1/ # .VNCH_soy,l = J’soy_max [1 99 where a), represents allocated pest control services (the proportion of reduction in pest density) in crop cell 1. Finally, the net return for corn under HM is given by: NRNCH _corn = Ipcorn 'ybase_corn — (1 + 2') ° VCcornI ' (Areatotal — AreaNCH) (22) which indicates that variable costs of corn production, VCcom, are also affected by the establishment of NCH by a factor of 1+}. because the non-temporary nature of the NCH. For each cell assigned to NCH that is not available for corn production, there is an opportunity cost of foregone income. The above expressions (equations (15)-(22)) apply to both farming systems with Eflicacyspmy=0 and C ostspmy=0 for the organic system and Efficacyspmpo and C ostspmy>0 for the conventional system. To assess the land use patterns under HM, we refer to relative economic performance of HM as compared to the baseline for each farming system. We define the proportion of change in net return to fixed factors from the baseline (nr) as: ____ NRNCH — NRbase : (NRNCH _soy + NRNCH _corn ) — (NRbase_soy + NRbase _corn) N Rbase (NRbase _ soy + N Rbase_ corn ) nr (23) Thus, the economic objective of the farmer is to choose the area and shape of NCH to maximize equation (23). 3.4 Numerical analysis Parameters Table 3.1 summarizes parameters used in the numerical analysis along with their sources, including literature, estimations from field data, estimations from secondary data, and assumptions. We use the simulation model developed by Costamagna et al. (2007b) to 100 predict three levels of average predation-free soybean aphid population density (aphids/plant) for the period of soybean plant growth stage R1 (reproductive stage one) to R5, corresponding to three levels of initial pest density as starting values for running the simulation model (30, 47 and 73 aphids/plant at the beginning of stage RI) taken from Michigan field data, assuming stage Rl begins on July 510. We assume the number of sprays needed is one for low and medium infestation levels (5000 and 8000 aphids/plant on average during R1 -R5, respectively) and two for high infestation level (12000 aphids/plant). The assumption is made based on results from Zhang (Essay 2), which suggests that, in the absence of predators, soybeans be sprayed twice for mean aphid density in stage R1 equal to or greater than 120 per plant, and once otherwise. This study rounds that value to 100, which corresponds to average density of 12000 aphids/plant for the period of stage R1 to R5. To measure how the variable costs of production change as the crop fields are re- configured to establish NCH, we focus on the change in machinery field time spent on turning. Turns are an important part of machinery field efficiency with turning time typically ranging from 12% to 15% of the total field time (Bowers, 1992). Assuming a width of 5 meters for crop strip (approximately 6 rows or 15 feet wide) and following operation modes as illustrated in Figures 3.6a to 36¢, we first count the approximate number of turns needed with and without NCH for all shapes and values of prop_NCH considered (Appendix D)1 1. We assume that 15% of the machinery field time is spent on 1° Data were provided in 2005 and 2006 by Alejandro Costamagna and Christine DiFonzo, Department of Entomology, Michigan State University. ” With archipelago, land cells are randomly assigned to either crop or NCH so that actual locations of NCH cells are not predictable given prop_NCH. We therefore assume the NCH cells are evenly distributed across the landscape and estimate the approximate number of turns that might be needed to operate on such fields. 101 turning in the baseline (no NCH), based on which any change in the number of turns made to accommodate NCH can be converted to change in the percentage of machinery time spent on turning. We then combine production cost data (UIUC, 2003) to estimate the amount of change in variable costs of production (3.) due to change in machinery field time for soybean and corn separately under both conventional and organic systems with cost savings on seed in NCH accounted for. The cost composition varies with types of farming system and with crop grown: the percentage of machinery cost (including repair, fuel, and hire) is highest for organic soybean (63%), followed by organic com (40%) (UIUC, 2003) (Appendix B). As Figures 3.7 and 3.8 show, field re-configuration can induce both positive and negative changes in the variable costs of production, depending on the shape and proportion of NCH. The overall magnitude of such changes remains small for the square and strip shapes (within the range of -4% to +4%), but can be remarkably high for the archipelago shape. Numerical results In the baseline, pesticide control proves to be cost-effective for conventional farms, saving 95% to 91% of the pest-free level of net return to fixed factors for the soybean- com rotation. By contrast, organic farms suffer significant loss to the new soybean pest ranging from 38% to 50% reduction in net returns, depending on the level of pest infestation that goes without any control as well as the distribution kernels used. As expected, the organic farms have a much higher stake than the conventional farms in considering HM as a potential pest control mechanism in the face of the new soybean pest. This conclusion is not only because of the difference in the baseline pest 102 management approaches, but also the considerable variability in the initial (pre-soybean aphid) net returns to fixed factors given the economic parameters assumed. Specifically, organic systems earn almost twice the level of net return conventional systems earn, mainly attributed to the price premium of organic products as well as a small variable costs advantage in producing organic com. This advantage exists in spite of the existence of yield disadvantages associated with both organic soybean and corn (Table 3.1). Our presentation of key results is focused on the medium infestation level and Laplace distribution kernel, followed by a discussion of the effects of pest pressure and differently shaped distribution kernels. Overall, 1% of NCH (prop_NCH=0.01) arranged in archipelago is found the optimal solution for HM approach to controlling soybean aphid among all configuration options considered. The land use pattern leads to an increase in net return by 59% from the no-control baseline under the organic system. For conventional farms, reliance on HM in lieu of insecticide-based aphid control reduces net returns in all simulations. However, NCH has the least negative effect at 1%, configured in an archipelago pattern, which results in a decrease by a mere 4% from the insecticide- based control baseline under the conventional system (Figure 3.8). The negative slope of the curves associated with archipelago after peaking at prop_NCH=0.01 implies a decreasing returns to scale effect of the area of NCH in the landscape, compounded by the opportunity cost of land use change and increased production cost due to farming a fragmented field (Figure 3.9). Due to the rapid rise in the estimated change in variable costs of production for archipelago as prop_NCH increases, the relative advantage of archipelago over square and strip at any given prop_NCH declines sharply once passing the peak at prop_NCH=0.01. In addition, the 103 performance of archipelago after the peak point declines at a much faster rate under the organic system than the conventional system as prop_NCH increases, partly because the estimated changes in variable costs of production under the organic system are about three times of those under the conventional system for the archipelago pattern. The effect of the variable costs change becomes more obvious in Figure 3.10 when such change is ignored (i.e., i=0), in which case the archipelago is preferred over the square and strip configurations at any given positive area of NCH within the relevant range. Between square and strip patterns, our results indicate that the strip pattern consistently shows better economic performance in both systems, although its comparative advantage is small under the conventional system (Figure 3.9). Specifically, 9% of NCH arranged in strips leads to the smallest reduction by 32% in net return under the conventional system, 0.2% smaller than the best achievable level that the square pattern can offer at prop_NCH=0. 1 6. Under the organic system, over 27% of improvement in net return can be expected at prop_NCH=0.05 for strip, 5% higher than the best achievable level by square at pr0p_NCH=0. l 5. Overall, the adoption of HM by a conventional system makes the farm worse off, which in the best scenario amounts to 4% reduction in net return as compared to the insecticide-based control baseline when NCH is established in archipelago pattern and accounts for 1% of total land area (Figure 3.9). The figure also shows that a conventional farm would be 54% worse off under the “doing nothing” scenario (i.e., prop_NCH=0) than applying insecticide to control the pest. In sharp contrast, the organic system gains significantly in economic performance after establishing NCH. Specifically, an organic farm would be better off than doing nothing by setting aside any positive amount of land 104 in strips or squares as habitats or 1-3% of land in an archipelago pattern to provide pest control services. With 1% of NCH arranged in an archipelago, the increase in net return reaches the highest level of 59%, more than twice the largest improvement the strip configuration can achieve with 5% of land devoted to NCH. While pest infestation level does not significantly influence the optimal choices with regard to the shape and area of NCH, it does play a role in determining the performance of HM relative to the baseline management. For instance, under the conventional system (and assuming a Laplace distribution kernel), the reductions in net return are 5% and 4% for low and medium infestation levels, respectively, given the optimal solution of 1% of NCH arranged in an archipelago pattern. At high infestation level, however, the same land use pattern leads to a slight increase in net return by 0.3%. This can be attributed to both the higher insecticide control cost under the high infestation scenario (when two applications of insecticides would be needed as compared to only one for low to medium pest levels) and the relatively lower return to insecticide control in the baseline as the number of pests escaped from the control tends to be higher when there is high infestation. Under the organic system, infestation levels have a more visible impact on the relative performance of HM. Specifically, the increases in net returns from the baseline are 41%, 59%, and 77% for low, medium, and high infestation levels, respectively, resulted from the same optimal configuration of NCH (i.e., 1% of NCH arranged in an archipelago). For square and strip patterns, higher pest pressure always corresponds to greater disadvantage (under the conventional system) or advantage (under the organic system) of HM relative to the baselines. For archipelago, however, there exists a threshold level of 105 NCH area (prop_NCH=0.l3), below which the gap between HM and chemical control gets smaller as infestation level increases under the conventional system, meaning that the higher the pest level is, the smaller the disadvantage of HM is as compared to the insecticide-based control baseline. Likewise, under the organic system, the higher the pest level, the better HM performs relative to the baseline for prop_NCH below 0.09. The result reflects the fact that archipelago contrasts with square and square patterns with respect to its superior ecological benefit and extraordinarily high production cost. When prop_NCH is relatively small (below the threshold levels), the farm benefits more from the ecological benefit associated with archipelago than suffering from increased production cost, including foregone yield. Higher pest levels simply exaggerate this effect. Given the parameters assumed, our results show that model outcomes are sensitive to the differently shaped distribution kernels used to describe the dispersal of natural pest control services around the NCH for square and strip patterns but remain robust to the choice of distribution kernel for archipelago. Given equal mean dispersal distance of 100 meters, the Laplace kernel is responsible for the best relative performance of HM as compared to the baseline (i.e., the most increase in net return under the organic system or the least reduction in net return under the conventional system), followed by Gaussian and cylindrical kernels for square and strip patterns (Figure 3.11). From the economic perspective, this result can be interpreted as “efficiency” difference between various dispersal modes of natural enemies or their services”. Coverage appears to be more important than intensity of control. When the landscape is mapped in a way that '2 Note that the distribution kernel is not a choice variable. Our analysis demonstrates that the distribution kernel implemented in the simulation model can have an impact on the economic outcomes, highlighting the need for better understanding of this important ecological factor. 106 each unit of land (i.e., cell) is sufficiently small as approached in this study, small patches of habitat as characterized by archipelago collectively deliver the same amount of control services across landscape, regardless of the dispersal patterns of natural enemies (Figure 3.1 I). This possibly raises another tradeoff relationship between the increase in production cost associated with field fragmentation and the robustness of overall ecological impact of habitats to natural enemy dispersal behavior. 3.5 Sensitivity analysis To investigate the effects of variations in a set of key spatial, ecological, and economic parameters, we perform sensitivity analyses on a specific case where infestation level is set at medium, natural pest control services are distributed according to a Laplace kernel, and the shape of NCH is strip. We look at how the relative performance of HM changes as values of these parameters are varied by 5% in both directions (except for the price of soybean, pm, which is varied by 10% in both directions). We report in Table 3.2 the percentage changes of the relative performance of HM from model outcomes based on parameters reported in Table 3.1 as a result of varying parameter values. Overall, model results are robust to parameter variations for the conventional system, except for efficacy rate of soybean aphid insecticides and natural enemy mean dispersal distance. Specifically, when decreasing Eflicacy,,,,,,y by 5% (no increase scenario is included because the baseline value is already 0.99), the advantage of chemical control relative to HM reduces by 18.4%. Extending (or reducing) the mean dispersal distance of natural enemies by 5 meters results in the advantage of chemical control over HM decreasing (or increasing) by 3.4%. The impacts of parameter variations 107 on model results under the organic system are generally stronger than those on the conventional system, because of the differentiated levels of yield potential and economic coefficients. In particular, model outcomes are most sensitive to variations in the mean dispersal distance and soybean price, followed by maximum soybean yield potential and the yield loss coefficient. 3.6 Conclusion and future research needs Natural enemies provide important ecosystem services to agriculture by suppressing pest damage to crop yield and also, less visibly, by maintaining an ecological equilibrium that prevents herbivore insects from reaching pest status. Enhancing this service by providing essential resources and compatible environment to natural enemies constitutes a potential alternative to the current insecticide-based pest management approach, which, in recent decades, has increased the frequency of pesticide resistance, pest outbreak and resurgence. The result is to make chemical control more costly and unreliable, and to produce unintended negative health outcomes for nontarget organisms, including humans (Thomas, 1999). This study explores economically optimal spatial habitat configuration for natural enemies of crop pests. The model developed here focuses on the simple function of non- crop habitats as sources of natural pest control services and evaluates the economic tradeoffs associated with land use choices between farming and setting aside land as natural enemy habitats. Not only is there an opportunity cost of forgone income from setting aside land, but the economic outcome is also highly dependent on the spatial 108 configuration of the non-crop habitats as well as the spatial distribution of natural control services into the surrounding crop fields. Our three main findings follow: First, non-crop habitat management is a promising pest management option for organic systems, not only because of their relatively high profitability, but also because of the constrained options in the pest management toolbox as compared to conventional systems. While any positive amount of habitat in square and strip shapes would guarantee an improvement in net return level from the no-control baseline, small area of habitat in archipelago results in the best outcome. Moreover, the higher the pest pressure is under an organic system, the greater the advantage of habitat management over the no-control management baseline, except when a relatively large area of habitat is arranged in high- cost archipelago shape. The adoption of habitat management in a conventional soybean-com system, however, tends to reduce farm net returns, highlighting the need for reducing the private cost of habitat management. In addition, it is important to note that the full economic value of the services from non-crop habitats is likely to be higher than that estimated from the private producer perspective in this study. Besides the social and environmental benefits from reducing the use of chemical insecticides, diversely structured agricultural landscapes tend to be positively related to other socially desirable ecological benefits such as habitats for beneficial insects and wildlife. Non-crop habitats could become attractive if policy were to reward all the ecosystem services due to their positive extemalities. Second, the shape and area of habitats are important factors in spatially optimal land use decisions. Land use patterns that devote a small amount of land to archipelago 109 habitat patches show the best economic performance in both systems. However, the benefit of fragmentation disappears rapidly as the area of habitat increases, leaving it inferior to strip and square patterns. While Bianchi and van der Werf (2003) find that better pest control is achieved in landscapes with a substantial area of non-crop habitats and where these habitats are distributed in small patches over the landscape, our analysis highlights the tradeoff between economic and ecological performance associated with the area and patchiness of habitat. From a private producer perspective, patchiness is only desirable when the total habitat area and configuration yield pest control benefits that balance the opportunity cost of land use change and increased production cost caused by field fragmentation. Third, the spatial distribution of natural control services to crop fields is an important factor determining the economic performance of habitat management. The simulation experiment in this study considers a simplified case in which natural pest control services are dispersed around a source origin into the crop fields within a certain range. The more complicated interactions associated with re-distribution and crowding of insect populations are ignored. Given equal mean dispersal distance assumed, we find positive association between the coverage (or spatial extent) of natural pest control services (as opposed to intensity of control) and the relative performance of habitat management for square and strip configurations. For archipelago, however, the use of different distribution kernels in the simulation model made no difference on the relative performance of habitat management. In practice, optimal habitat configuration is likely to be species specific, highlighting the need to rely on solid ecological knowledge in building models for management decision support. Economic parameters such as prices 110 of organic products and biological parameters such as the pest mortality rate due to insecticides also have important impact on the model results. Several issues deserve future attention. First, while not considered in the current study, species scale dependence may have important implications for spatially explicit models involving land use choices. If natural enemy density increases exponentially with area of contiguous habitat, the aggregation of patchy habitats may become desirable and coordinated action among multiple land managers may become socially desirable. Future research into habitat management may also benefit from enhanced capability to link actual natural enemy population density with the size of non-crop habitats. Such linkage would allow us to explore more species-targeted management practices as well as integrated approaches that combine natural control with chemical control. Second, obtaining improved parameter estimates (such as the efficacy rate of insecticides and species spatial distribution scale parameters) represents an important direction to strengthen such interdisciplinary research. The relationship between the area and spatial configuration of non-crop habitats in the landscape and the density of natural enemies remains a highly relevant ecological question to be explored. F urtherrnore, the estimation of the pest regulation effect of non-crop habitats could greatly benefit from the use of empirical data. Finally, given the spatial nature of the dispersal of natural enemies and their services, issues of extemalities and spillovers will arise, which may influence the design of socially optimal policy incentives. While the model developed here is capable of investigating such issues at the landscape scale, it is beyond the scope of the current analysis. Future research may also look into potential opportunities for bundling habitat III management policies with other policy incentives that address issues such as water pollution and soil conservation. Two factors are particularly important when thinking about socially optimal land use choices: the distribution of natural enemies in space and the scale dependence effect. The latter offers a potential gain in total control services generated from a larger contiguous non-crop habitat if species population increases disproportionately with habitat size, whereas a longer dispersal distance as described by the Laplace kernel ensures that the services reach more crop fields. For instance, strip habitats near farm borders may produce better collective outcomes than individual farms establishing their own habitats of equal area. Parkhurst et al. (2002) conduct an experiment to explore a voluntary incentive mechanism, the agglomeration bonus, designed to protect endangered species and biodiversity by reuniting fragmented habitat across private land. The mechanism provides incentives for non-cooperative landowners to voluntarily create a contiguous reserve across their common border (Parkhurst et al., 2002). Such policy mechanisms may be useful when models like the one developed here show coordination benefits to optimal spatial configuration of non-crop habitats. 112 References Aerts, J .C.J .H., M. van Herwijnen, R. Janssen, and T.J. Stewart. 2005. “Evaluating spatial design techniques for solving land-use allocation problems.” Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 48(1): 121-142. Barbosa, P. 1998. Conservation Biological Control. San Diego CA: Academic Press. Bianchi, F.J.J.A., C.J.H. Booij, and T. Tschamtke. 2006. “Sustainable pest regulation in agricultural landscapes: a review on landscape composition, biodiversity and natural pest control.” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London Series B- Biological Sciences 273 : l 71 5-1 727. Bianchi, F .J .J .A., A. Honek, and W. van der Werf. 2007. In press. “Linking land use patterns to population viability: implications for conservation biological control.” Landscape Ecology. Bianchi, F.J.J.A., and W. van der Werf. 2003. “The effect of the area and configuration of hibernation sites on the control of aphids by Coccinella septempunctata (Coleoptera: Coccinellidae) in agricultural landscapes: a simulation study.” Environmental Entomology 32(6): 1290-1304. Brown, C., L. Lynch, and D. Zilberrnan. 2002. “The economics of controlling insect- transmitted plant diseases.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 84: 279- 291. Bowers, W. 1992. Machinery Management. Moline IL: Deere & Company. Costamagna, A.C. 2006. “Do varying natural enemy assemblages impact Aphis glycines population dynamics?” PhD Dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Costamagna, A.C., D.A. Landis, and CD. DiFonzo. 2007a. “Suppression of soybean aphid by generalist predators results in a trophic cascade in soybeans.” Ecological Applications 17(2):441—45 1 . Costamagna, A.C., W. van der Werf, F .J.J.A. Bianchi, and D.A. Landis. 2007b. “An exponential growth model with decreasing r captures bottom-up effects on the population growth of Aphis glycines Matsumura (Hemiptera: Aphididae).” Agricultural and Forest Entomology 9: 1—9. Cousens, R. 1985. “A simple model relating yield loss to weed density.” Annals of Applied Biology 107: 239-252. 113 DiFonzo, CD, and R. Hines. 2002. “Soybean aphid in Michigan: update from the 2001 season.” Michigan State University Extension Bulletin E-2748, East Lansing, MI. Fox, T.B., D.A. Landis, F.F. Cardoso, and CD. DiFonzo. 2004. “Predators suppress Aphis glycines Matsumura population growth in soybean.” Environmental Entomology 33(3): 608-618. Hambaeck, RA, and G. Englund. 2005. “Patch area, population density and the scaling of migration rates: the resource concentration hypothesis revisited.” Ecology Letters 8: 1057-1065. Hof, J ., and M. Bevers. 1998. Spatial Optimization for Managed Ecosystems. New York: Columbia University Press. Hof, J .G., M. Bevers, and B. Kent. 1997. ”An optimization approach to area-based fest pest management over time and space.” Forest Science 43(1): 121-128. Hof, J .G., and LA. Joyce. 1992. “Spatial optimization for wildlife and timber in managed forest ecosystems.” Forest Science 38(3): 489-508. Landis, D.A., S.D. Wratten, and GM. Gurr. 2000. “Habitat management to conserve natural enemies of arthropod pests in agriculture.” Annual Review of Entomology 45: 175-201. Landis, D.A., F.D. Menalled, A.C. Costamagna, and T.K. Wilkinson. 2005. “Manipulating plant resources to enhance beneficial arthropods in agricultural landscapes.” Weed Science 53: 902-908. Losey, J .E., and M. Vaughan. 2006. “The economic value of ecological services provided by insects.” Bioscience 56(4): 331-323. McKeown, CH. 2003. “Quantifying the roles of competition and niche separation in native and exotic Coccinellids, and the changes in the community in response to an exotic prey species.” MS Thesis, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Nalle, D.J., CA. Montgomery, J.L. Arthur, S. Polasky, and NH. Schumaker. 2004. “Modeling joint production of wildlife and timber.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48: 997-1017. Naylor, R., and P. Ehrlich. 1997. “Natural pest control services and agriculture.” In G. Daily, ed. Nature 's Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Washington DC: Island Press, pp. 151 -74. Parkhurst, G.M., J.F. Shogren, C. Bastian, P. Kivi, J. Donner, and R.B.W. Smith. 2002. “Agglomeration bonus: an incentive mechanism to reunite fragmented habitat for biodiversity conservation.” Ecological Economics 41: 305-328. 114 Polasky, S., E. Nelson, E. Lonsdorf, P.L. Fackler, and A. Starfield. 2005. “Conserving species in a working landscape: land use with biological and economic objectives.” Ecological Applications 15(4): 1387-1401. Root, RB. 1973. “Organization of a plant-arthropod association in simple and diverse habitats: the fauna of collards (Brassica oleracea).” Ecological Monographs 43: 95-124. Rutledge, C.E., R.J. O'Neil, T.B. Fox, and D.A. Landis. 2004. “Soybean aphid predators and their use in 1PM.” Annals of the Entomological Society of America 97:240- 248. Sanchirico, IN, and J .E. Wilen. 2000. “Dynamics of spatial exploitation: a metapopulation approach.” Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 00-25- REV, Washington, DC. Seppelt, R., and A. Voinov. 2002. “Optimization methodology for land use patterns using spatially explicit landscape models.” Ecological Modeling 151: 125-142. Skelsey, P., W.A.H. Rossing, G.J.T. Kessel, J. Powell, and W. van der Werf. 2005. “Influence of host diversity on development of epidemics: an evaluation and elaboration of mixture theory.” Phytopathology 95(4): 328-338. The MathWorks Inc. 1994-2007. MatLab Function Reference. Natick, MA. Thies, C., I. Steffan-Dewenter, and T. Tschamtke. 2003. “Effects of landscape context on herbivory and parasitism at different spatial scales.” Oikos 101: 18-25. Thies, C., and T. Tschamtke. 1999. “Landscape structure and biological control in agroecosystems.” Science 285(5429): 893-895. Thomas, MB. 1999. “Ecological approaches and the development of ‘truly integrated’ pest management.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 96: 5944-5951. Tilman, D. 1999. “Global environmental impacts of agricultural expansion: the need for sustainable and efficient practices.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 96(May): 5995-6000. Turner, M.G., G.J. Arthaud, R.T. Engstrom, S.J. Hejl, J. Liu, S. Loeb, and K. McKelvey. 1995. “Usefulness of spatially explicit population models in land management.” Ecological Applications 5(1 ): 12-16. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign (UIUC). 2003. “Illinois specialty farm products.” Department of Agricultural and Consumer Economics. http://webacesuiuc.edu/value/factsheets 115 US. Department of Agriculture (USDA). 2000. “2000 Agricultural Resource Management Survey.” Washington DC. http://www.ncrlc.com/GR-campaign- webpages/US-farm-stats.html Welland, R., and D. Smith, 2007. “Metric conversions.” Ag Decision Maker, File C6-80. Iowa State University, University Extension, Ames, IA. http://www.extension. iastate.edu/AGDM/wholefarm/pdf/C6-80g)_df Zhang, W. Essay 2. “Optimal Control of Soybean Aphid in the Presence of Natural Enemies.” PhD dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. 116 Table 3.1: Values of parameters used in the numerical analysis and their sources or estimations Parameters Values Sources n: proportion of yield lost per unit 0.00026 Estimated from Michigan field data of pest population for 2005 provided by Christine DiFonzo ,u: maximum allowable yield loss 1 Model restriction pmy conventional $247.9/tonl3 UIUC (2003) Food-Grade pm, organic $518/ton UIUC (2003) Food-Grade pm", conventional $85.1/ton UIUC (2003) Regular hybrid pcom organic $133.2/ton UIUC (2003), Feed grade ym_,oy conventional 3.08 ton/ha UIUC (2003) Food-Grade ymax ,0, organic 2.45 ton/ha UIUC (2003) Food-Grade ym_c,,,,, conventional 10.85 ton/ha UIUC (2003) Regular hybrid ymax can, organic 9.45 ton/ha UIUC (2003) Feed grade VCsoy conventional $260/ha UIUC (2003) Food-Grade VCW organic $260/ha UIUC (2003) F ood-Grade VCcom conventional $490/ha UIUC (2003) Regular hybrid VCm, organic $472.5/ha UIUC (2003) Feed grade pest,,,,~,,-,,,: control-free pest 5000 (low), 8000 Predicted from Costamagna et al. infestation level (avg soybean (medium), and (2007b) model with starting values aphid density during soybean 12000 (high) taken from Michigan field data plant stages R1 through R5) aphids/plant Cost,,,,,,y: cost of spray per $30.5/ha Song et al. (2006) application Number_of_sprays Eflicacyspmy: efficacy rate of soybean aphid insecticides r: radius of cylindrical kernel a: slope of the decline of allocated services with distance for Laplace kernel 6: standard deviation of Gaussian kernel Avg. percentage of reduction in pest density responding to the percentage of NCH in landscape 2.: Proportion of change in variable costs due to the establishment of NCH 1 for low, medium infestation; 2 for high infestation 0.99 100 m 0.02 m'1 80 m See Figure 3.4 See Figure 3.7-3.8 Adapted from results in essay 2 Assumed Assumed Assumed Assumed Estimated from simulation results from Bianchi and van der Werf (2003) Estimated using cost data from UIUC (2003) and estimate of the amount of machinery field time spent on turning (Bowers, 1992) (Appendix D) '3 1 metric ton = 36.74 (37) bushels soybeans (60 pound bu) and 1 bushel/acre = 0.0673 (0.07) metric tons/hectare (Weiland and Smith, 2007). 1 hectare = 2.471 (2.5) acres 117 Table 3.2: Summary of sensitivity analysis results (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel, and strip NCH) Changes in outcomes (nr associated with optimal prop NCH) from baseline“ Parameters Conventional Organic n: proportion of yield lost per unit of pest T5%: I 1.4% T5%: T 3.3% population I5%: T 1.5% I5%: I 3.3% pm, T10%: I 2.3% T10%: T 6.8% I10%: T 2.7% I10%: I 7.2% ymaxgw, T5%: I 1.2% T5%: T 3.5% I5%: T 1.3% I5%: I 3.5% VCmy T5%: I 1.1 % T5%: T 1.7% I5%: T 1% I5%: I 1.6% Cost,,,,,,.: cost of spray per application T5%: T 0.4 % I5%: I 0.4% Efiicacyspmy: efiicacy rate of soybean aphid I5%: T 18.4% insecticides Mean dispersal distance (2/a) T5%: T 3.4% T5%: T 5.2% I5%: I 3.4% I5%: I 5.1% Avg. percentage of reduction in pest density T5%: T 0.5% T5%: T 0.7% responding to the percentage of NCH in I5%: I 0.5 % I5%: I 0.8 % landscape * The baseline refers to model outcomes based on parameters given in Table 3.1. 118 i=I,...,N Figure 3.1: The distribution of land between non-crop habitats, impact zone, and no impact zone 119 -1500 -1000 -500 O 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.2a: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80X80 grid and with pro_NCH=0.l): Square 120 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.2b: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80X80 grid and with pro_NCH=0.l): Strip 121 -2000 ' ' -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.2c: Illustration of landscape configuration with four farms and three NCH configurations (prepared in 80X80 grid and with pro_NCH=0.l): Archipelago 122 0.02.........._... 0,01 _q 4000 Figure 3.3a: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200x200 grid): Cylindrical kernel (radius=100 m) 123 0.02.. --------- " ....... 600 4000 -1000 Figure 3.3b: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200x200 grid): Laplace kernel (a=0.02 m") 124 0,02,. ........... " .......... 0015 .. ............................. 0.01 m ~1000 4000 4000 Figure 3.3c: Illustration of distribution kernels (prepared in 200x200 grid): Gaussian kernel (0=80 m) 125 80% 60% // 40% Reduction of pest density (%) 20% / 0% T fi T l I T T I I 1 T fl T I 1 T 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 12% 14% 16% NCH area (%) Figure 3.4: The relationship between the NCH area and the average pest reduction impact (Estimated from Bianchi and van der Werf, 2003) 126 2000 1 500 1 000 500 O -500 -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 —1500 -1000 —500 O 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(i)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400x400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Square 127 1500 ‘03 r 1 0.8 1000. .0] 500 05 0 f 0.5 _500 04 -1000 -1500 -2000 - -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(i)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400x400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Strip 128 2000 1 500 1000 500 -500 -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 —1500 —1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(i)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400x400 grid: Cylindrical kernel; Archipelago 129 2000 1500 "0'9 -0.8 1000 . 0.7 500 ; 0.6 o 0.5 _500 0.4 -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 O 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(ii)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.1 in a 400x400 grid: Laplace kernel; Square 130 2000 1500 '09 -00 1000 -0] 500 05 o 05 _500 0A -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(ii)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400x400 grid: Laplace kernel; Strip 131 2000 4 0.3 1 500 1000 “ 0-25 500 0'2 0 0.1 5 -500 -1000 -1500 -2000 , -2000 -1500 —1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(ii)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400x400 grid: Laplace kernel; Archipelago 132 2000 1500 " 0'9 : 0.8 1000 - 0.7 50° ' 0.6 o 0.5 _500 0.4 -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(iii)a: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400X400 grid: Gaussian kernel; Square 133 1500 ‘0'9 “0.8 1000} -o.7 soo , 0.6 o f 0.5 _500 0.4 0.3 4000 r 0.2 -1500 0.1 -2000 o A -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(iii)b: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400X400 grid: Gaussian kernel; Strip 134 2000 _— 0.35 150° . 0.3 1000 . 0.25 500 02 0 0.15 -500 ' -1000 -1500 -2000 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 Figure 3.5(iii)c: Illustration of distributions of pest control impact (proportion of reduction), prepared with prop_NCH=0.l in a 400x400 grid: Gaussian kernel; Archipelago 135 JV «((t:<<<<¢¢<())»»>3):3»)>)>»»u»y»)»»))) (..(«t(tti¢(((t((««41((((««(ii:tt A (the 10!] Illustration of assumed modes of machinery field operat Figure 3.6b Strip number “1” represents one turn) 137 S ’ C 0 ’ ( ) ) ¢ ’ ) V > } ( ) ) ( ) 0 1 I } T i 3 ( ) 0 ( i ) ¢ 1‘ L G c ( ( < ( ¢ 4 1 b D b ) i so ) I > D t j ( C ( V 8 ( ( t ( ( ( ’ , ) ’ ’ ) ’ i F . ’ ) .1 t C v a. 0 t 1 ( 1 i 0 ) ) \. .r ) t s. s. ) .2 d c ( ¢ ( c (.1 ( lago l 3 8 1 Arch Figure 3.6c: Illustration of assumed modes of machinery field operation (the ipe number “1” represents one turn) 2% A O 33 m '8’ 0% U 5 § 4% 2 ° 4% -5% ”xx-M 9x ‘u.—‘-,~ 7‘. Ff ,7 j’ f r I T - ‘ J~ 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10%11%12%13%14%15%16% Percentage of NCH -—+— conv_com_squane —s— conv_soy_square - + — org_com_square —-><——-— org_soy_square - - x - - conv_com_strip —o——conv_soy_strip - - -+« - - org_com_stn'p org_soy__strip Figure 3.7: Estimated values of the percentage of change in variable costs of production for square and strip patterns 139 Change in variable cost (%) j, 1 1 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10%11%12%13%14%15%16% Percentage of NCH + conv_com + conv_soy + org_com + org_soy Figure 3.8: Estimated values of the percentage of change in variable costs of production for archipelago pattern 140 Proportion of change in nr from baseline . l -2 "‘ -. I . ‘I -2.5 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 Proportion of NCH + Square (conv) —9—-— Strip (conv) — - s - - Archipelago (conv) —-—+—— Square (organic) —0— Strip (organic) - - -e- - - Archipelago (organic) Figure 3.9: Proportion of change in net return to fixed factors (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel) 141 0.1 T.“I-_..‘ I ‘-‘__‘ O r] r ‘1 a j Wi f r r r r r T r fl ~-..‘ . 1 ~.._‘ ' "“s -01 ' ""r 43......“ e I “.1 1 -0.2 .L Proportion of change in nr from baseline 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 Proportion of NCH —e— Square (conv) —<;~— Strip (conv) — - s - — Archipelago (conv) Figure 3.10: Proportion of change in net return to fixed factors for a conventional farm when change in variable costs of production is ignored (Medium pest infestation, Laplace kernel) 142 Square + Cylindrical (COM) —0— Laplace (00ml) - 1 - - Gaussian (60M —.— Cylindrical ' (organic) —6— Laplace ..—I—-c-—I--'l'—O""""'.'""" (organic) Proportion 01 change in nr from baseline . —I- - I - -I-' ----- -- Gaussian (organic) 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 Proportion of NCH Strip + Cylindrical (00M —0— Laplace (60PM — -- - - Gaussian (coma baseline —s——Cylindrical (weenie) r —0— Laplace (orsariC) -~-I- -- Gaussian as - -__ ._ -_ -2 , - (organic) 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 ProportionofNCH Proportion of change in nr tram Archipelago + Conventional 1 —0— Organic Proportion of change in nr from baseline 1 o 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 0.14 0.16 Proportion of NCH Figure 3.11: The effect of distribution kernels on the relative performance of HM at medium pest infestation 143 Conclusions The three essays of this dissertation explore two approaches to managing natural pest control ecosystem services in order to achieve improved pest management in agricultural systems. Essays 1 and 2 focus on integrating natural pest control into insecticide decision-making so that natural enemies of crop pests are conserved and efficiently used to the extent that the marginal factor cost of insecticide application (including the opportunity cost of natural enemy mortality from insecticides) balances the marginal value of the yield benefit. Essay 3 moves beyond insecticide-based pest management to look at optimal spatial land use decisions for the management of habitats of natural enemies. By conserving (or better utilizing) and enhancing the natural pest control services, there are new opportunities for improving pest management in an economically appealing and socially desirable manner. To promote such opportunities would require not only a tremendous increase in scientific understanding of ecosystems, but also major innovations to our economic and social institutions to capture this value and incorporate it into day-to-day decision-making (Daily and Ellison, 2002). The approach presented here offers a useful framework for the management of other supporting and regulating ecosystem services that serve as inputs to biological production of marketed agricultural products. The three essays employ bioeconomic modeling and optimization analysis to explore the economic consequences of these opportunities on private producers. According to these experiments, there are clearly economic gains from incorporating natural enemies into insecticide decisions, which effectively delays and reduces the need 144 for insecticide spraying. The economic advantage of establishing non-crop habitats in agricultural landscape, however, depends on the alternative pest management practices available. For instance, relying on non-crop habitats of natural enemies for the management of pests may not be economically viable if chemical control remains a cost- effective option, as under a conventional farming system. The relevant policy question, therefore, is how to develop policy instruments 1) to promote the adoption of natural enemy-incorporated insecticide strategies that have the potential to improve economic returns to private producers, and ii) to provide private producers with needed economic incentives to adopt sustainable pest management approaches, such as habitat management, that enhance the natural pest control services. In the second case, values of ecological and environmental benefits from the establishment of non-crop habitats (e.g., enhanced ecosystem services provided by beneficial pollinator insects) may be of interest because they help justify the social incentives for supporting such practices. Results from Essay 3 show the magnitude of reduction in private net returns to fixed factors of production as a result of habitat management. Such estimates may serve as a lower bound for the financial support needed for conventional farmers to adopt habitat management voluntarily. At the landscape scale, coordination issues are also relevant to the management of natural pest control services when spillovers exist for the distribution of natural control benefits and the costs due to nontarget natural enemy mortality from insecticides. The spillover of natural control benefits may reduce private incentives for voluntary adoption due to the free-rider problem. Because of the nontarget natural enemy mortality from insecticides, even if some farmers decide to adopt biological pest control strategies, they 145 could be harmed by pesticide use on neighboring farms (Wilson and Tisdell, 2001). Such spillover effects would require individual farmers to coordinate action in adopting sustainable management approaches if economic losses are to be avoided (Wilson and Tisdell, 2001). Finally, scale matters for natural enemy habitats that may affect socially optimal spatial land use choices. If natural enemy density increases disproportionately with size of habitat, the aggregation of patchy habitats through coordinated action may become socially desirable. 146 References Daily, G.C., and K. Ellison. 2002. The New Economy of Nature-The Quest to Make Conservation Profitable. Washington DC: Island Press/Shearwater Books. Wilson, C., and C. Tisdell. 2001. “Why farmers continue to use pesticides despite environmental, health and sustainability costs.” Ecological Economics 39: 449- 462. 147 Appendix A: MatLab code for the optimal insecticide management model (Essay 2) %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% Single-season optimizing simulation model: Interaction between soybean aphid, natural enemies, and soybean yield Author: Wei Zhang, 2007 % % g % % Soybean aphid population growth module developed by Felix Bianchi, % Alejandro Costamagna, and Wopke van der Werf, May 2005 (Costamagna et % al., 2007), and modified by Wei Zhang % % % % % % % Reference: Costamagna, A.C., W. van der Werf, F.J.J.A. Bianchi, and D.A. Landis. 2007. “An exponential growth model with decreasing r captures bottom- up effects on the population growth of Aphis glycines Matsumura Hemiptera: Aphididae)." Agricultural and Forest Entomology 9:1—9. %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% clc % PARAMETERS % SIMULATION TIME STEP DELT=1; % SBA DAILY POPULATION GROWTH FITTED BY WILLIAMS MODEL: Estimated from the generalized model RGRMAX = 0.3978; % corresponds to the first infestation date at KBS in 2005, which is approximately 6/23/05 C = 0.0240; % Kill rate of insecticides KI = 0.99; KN = 0.99; % Death rate of natural enemy D1 = 0; D2 = -O.9; D3 = -2.l3; % Birth rate of natural enemy due to consumption of SBA B1 =0; BZ =0; B3 = 0.002; % Percentage of yield loss due to 1 unit of SBA YDl = 0; YD2 = 0; YD3 = 0.0003; YD4 = 0.0001;- YDS = 0; % Percentage of maximum yield loss YMl = 1; % restricted to be one YM2 = l; YM3 = 1; YM4 = l; YM5 - 1‘ % CONTROL COST 148 COST =12.18; % OUTPUT PRICE PRICE =6.91; %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% % SBA population density for each stage in the absence of predation %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% fid = fopen('SBA_no_predation_26JulO7.txt','w'); % PLANT GROWTH STAGE % At KBS in 2005, R1 approximately began on July 5 % Mean R-stage length data from literature: 3,10,9,9,15 days DATEOR1_KBS = datenum('7/5/2005'); DATE1R1_KBS = datenum('7/7/2005'); DATEOR2_KBS = datenum('7/8/2005'); DATE1R2_KBS = datenum('7/l7/2005'); DATEOR3_KBS = datenum('7/18/2005'); DATE1R3_KBS = datenum('7/26/2005'); DATEOR4_KBS = datenum('7/27/2005'); DATE1R4_KBS = datenum('8/4/2005'); DATEOR5_KBS = datenum('8/5/2005'); DATE1R5_KBS = datenum('8/19/2005'); R1_KBS = DATE1R1_KBS-DATEOR1_KBS+1; % Number of days during R1 R2_KBS = DATE1R2_KBS~DATEOR2_KBS+1; R3_KBS = DATE1R3_KBS—DATEOR3_KBS+1; R4_KBS = DATE1R4_KBS-DATEOR4_KBS+1; R5_KBS = DATE1R5_KBS-DATEOR5_KBS+1; L_KBS = R1_KBS+R2_KBS+R3_KBS+R4_KBS+R5_KBS; % Initial conditions (SBA/plant) I=73.45; % KBS, mean of multiple plots, 7/5/05 TIME=O; % R1 Time Loop: FINISH TIME or SIMULATION (DAY) TIME_KBS =L_KBS; while TIME no pest control, no control cost %%%%%%% for ncadist=1:3 for p = 0 % NCH area (percentage of total landscape area) reduc 0 % pest reduction (%) corresponding to p shape farm r1 = 0 % Proportion of pest reduction (i.e. measurable actual impact) r2 = r3 = 0 O cp_s = 0 % Proportion of change in variable cost of production for soybean due to establishing NCH under conventional system cp_c = 0 % Proportion of change in variable cost of production for soybean due to establishing NCH under conventional system pestl = pesto * (1 - r1) pest2 = pesto * (1 - r2) pest3 = pesto * (1 - r3) dml = (d1 * pestl)./(1 + (d1 * pestl / d2 )) dm2 (d1 * pest2)./(1 + (d1 * pest2 / d2 )) dm3 = (d1 * pest3)./(1 + (d1 * pest3 / d2 )) y1_s1 = (shape * (~1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm1)) % Actual soybean yield (bu/ac) y1_s2 = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm2)) y1_s3 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (l - dm3)) spi1_celll = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sl * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) % Soybean profit per CELL spi1_ce112 = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sZ * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) spi1_cell3 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_s3 * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) cpil_cell = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y0_c * price_c - pcost_c * (1 + cp~C)) * (dx * dy /10000) % Corn profit given NCH taken out of production rotpi1_celll rotation rotpil_cell2 rotpi1_ce113 spi1_celll + cpi1_cell % Profit per soybean-corn spil_ce112 + cpilficell spi1_cell3 + cpi1_cell tpil_farml = sum(sum(rotpi1_celll)) % profit per rotation per farm tpil_farmz = sum(sum(rotpi1_ce112)) tpil_farm3 = sum(sum(rotpi1_ce113)) 156 tpil_lsl 4* tpil_farml % profit for landscape tpil_lsz 4* tpil_farm2 tpil_ls3 = 4* tpil_farm3 % Change in soybean profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farm_sl = ( (sum(sum(spi1_celll))) - (sum(sum(spio_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_sz = ( (sum(sum(spi1_ce112))) - (sum(sum(spio_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spio_cell))) change_farm_sB = ( (sum(sum(spi1_cell3))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) % Change in rotation profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farml = (tpil_farml - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm2 = (tpil_farm2 — tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm3 = (tpil_farm3 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm % Change in rotation profit at the landscape scale from baseline change_lsl (tpil_lsl - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_ls2 (tpil_lsZ - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_lsB (tpil_ls3 - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls checkl = change_lsl - change_farml check2 = change_lsz — change_farm2 check3 = change_ls3 - change_farm3 % Output output=[farmingsystem; n; pesto; n_spray; p; reduc; alpha; beta; cp_s; cp_c; ncadist; change_farm_sl; change_farm_sz; change_farm_s3; change_farml; change_farm2; change_farm3;change_ls1; change_lsz; change_lsB]; fprintf(fid,'%12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.4f %12.4f %12.0f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f\n', output); end end %%%%%%%%%% Square %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% for ncadist = 1 % Landscapes with square NCH for p = 1:1:16 if p == 1 cp_s = 0.001 cp_c = 0 elseif p == 2 cp_s = 0.001 cp_c = —0.001 elseif p == 3 cp_s = 0 cp_c = -0.002 elseif p == 4 cp_s = -0.001 cp_c = -0.003 elseif p == 5 cp_s = -0.002 cp_c = -0.004 157 reduc=i to p elseif p == 6 cp_s = -0.004 cp_c = -0.005 elseif p == 7 cp_s = -0.005 cp_c = -0.007 elseif p == 8 cp_s = -0.006 cp_c = -0.008 elseif p == 9 cp_s = —0.007 cp_c = -0.010 elseif p == 10 cp_s = -0.009 cp_c = -0.011 elseif p == 11 cp_s = -0.010 cp_c = -0.013 elseif p == 12 cp_s = -0.011 cp_c = —0.014 elseif p == 13 cp_s = -0.013 cp_c = -0.015 elseif p == 14 cp_s = -0.014 cp_c = -0.017 elseif p == 15 cp_s = -0.016 cp_c = -0.018 elseif p == 16 cp_s = -0.017 cp_c = -0.020 end nterp1(pp, reduc_data, p) % pest reduction (%) corresponding s = round(sqrt (n*2*(p/100)/4)/2) * 2 % Define size of the NCH squares square = [zeros(n/4-s/2,n/2); zeros(s,n/4-s/2) ones(s) zeros(s,n/4- s/2); zeros(n/4—s/2,n/2)] size_of source shape = _square = 5‘2 * dx * dy = square * dx * dy * a1pha*(size_of_square)‘beta square totalsource = sum(sum(source)) fsource impactl impact2 impact3 = fft2(source) = max(0, real(fftshift(ifft2(fK1 .* fsource)))) = real(fftshift(ifft2(fK2 .* fsource))) = real(fftshift(ifft2(fK3 .* fsource))) % Balance check: total impact must be equal before and after distributi afterl after2 on over the landscape = sum(sum(impact1)) = sum(sum(impact2)) 158 after3 = sum(sum(impact3)) before = sum(sum(source)) relerrl = (afterl — before)/before relerr2 (after2 - before)/before relerr3 = (after3 - before)/before relimpactl = impactl/totalsource relimpact2 impact2/totalsource relimpact3 impact3/totalsource ic = sum(sum(shape *(-1) + 1)) crop_impactl = (shape * (-1) + 1) crop_impact2 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* impact2 crop_impact3 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* impact3 tcrop_impactl sum(sum(crop_impact1)) tcrop_impact2 sum(sum(crop_impact2)) tcrop_impact3 sum(sum(crop_impact3)) .* impactl r1 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impactl) .* crop_impactl ) r2 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact2) .* crop_impact2 ) r3 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact3) .* crop_impact3 ) pestl = pesto * (1 - r1) pest2 = pesto * (l — r2) pest3 = pesto * (1 - r3) dml = (d1 * pestl)./(1 + (d1 * pestl / d2 )) dm2 = (d1 * pest2)./(1 + (d1 * pest2 / d2 )) dm3 = (d1 * pest3)./(1 + (d1 * pest3 / d2 )) y1_sl = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 — dm1)) % Actual soybean yield (bu/ac) y1_52 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm2)) y1_s3 = (shape * {-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm3)) spi1_celll = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sl * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) % Soybean profit per CELL spi1_ce112 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sz * price_s — pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) spilficellB = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_s3 * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) cpi1_cell = (shape * pcost_c * (1 + cp_c)) * out of production (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y0_c * price_c - (dx * dy /10000) % Corn profit given NCH taken rotpi1_ce111 rotation rotpi1_ce112 rotpi1_ce113 spi1_celll + cpi1_cell % Profit per soybean-corn spi1_ce112 + spi1_cell3 + cpi1_cell cpi1_cell tpil_farml = tpil_farm2 = tpil_farm3 = sum(sum(rotpi1_celll)) sum(sum(rotpi1_ce112)) sum(sum(rotpi1_ce113)) % profit per rotation per farm tpil_lsl tpil_lsz tpil_ls3 4* tpil_farml % profit for landscape 4* tpil_farm2 4* tpil_farm3 159 % Change in soybean profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farm_sl = ( (sum(sum(spi1_celll))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_sZ = ( (sum(sum(spi1_ce112))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_s3 = ( (sum(sum(spi1_ce113))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) % Change in rotation profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farml = (tpil_farml — tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm2 (tpil_farm2 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm3 = (tpil_farm3 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm % Change in rotation profit at the landscape scale from baseline change_lsl = (tpil_lsl - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_lsz = (tpil_lsZ - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_lsB = (tpil_ls3 — tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls checkl = change_lsl - change_farml check2 = change_lsZ - change_farm2 check3 = change_ls3 - change_farm3 % Output output=[farmingsystem; n; pesto; n_spray; p; reduc; alpha; beta; cp_s; cp_c; ncadist; change_farm_sl; change_farm_sz; change_farm_sB; change_farml; change_farm2; change_farm3;change_lsl; change_lsZ; change_lsB]; fprintf(fid,'%12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.4f %12.4f %12.0f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f\n', output); end end %%%%%%%%%% Strip %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% for ncadist = 2 % Landscapes with strip NCH for p = 1:1:16 if p == 1 cp_s = —0.002 cp_c = —0.002 elseif p == 2 cp_s = -0.004 cp_c = -0.004 elseif p == 3 cp_s = -0.006 cp_c = —0.006 elseif p == 4 cp_s = -0.009 cp_c = -0.008 elseif p == 5 cp_s = —0.011 cp_c = -0.010 elseif p == 6 cp_s = -0.013 cp_c = -0.012 elseif p == 7 160 cp_s = -0.015 cp_c = —0.014 elseif p == 8 cp_s = -0.017 cp_c = -0.016 elseif p == 9 cp_s = -0.019 cp_c = —0.018 elseif p == 10 cp_s = ~0.021 cp_c = -0.020 elseif p == 11 cp_s = -0.023 cp_c = -0.022 elseif p == 12 cp_s = -0.026 cp_c = -0.024 elseif p == 13 cp_s = -0.028 cp_c = -0.026 elseif p == 14 cp_s = -0.030 cp_c = -0.028 elseif p == 15 cp_s = -0.032 cp_c = -0.030 elseif p == 16 cp_s = —0.034 cp_c = ~0.032 end reduc=interp1(pp, reduc_data, p) % pest reduction (%) corresponding to p w = max(round((n‘2 * (p/lOO)/4)/(n/2)),1) % Define width of the strips strip = [zeros(n/4-round(w/2),n/2);ones(w,n/2);zeros(n/2—w-(n/4- round(w/2)),n/2)] size_of_strip = w * n/2 * dx * dy source = strip * dx * dy * alpha*(size_of_strip)‘beta shape = strip totalsource = sum(sum(source)) fsource = fft2(source) impactl = max(0, real(fftshift(ifft2(fK1 .* fsource)))) impact2 = real(fftshift(ifft2(fK2 .* fsource))) impact3 = real(fftshift(ifft2(fK3 .* fsource))) % Balance check: total impact must be equal before and after distribution over the landscape afterl = sum(sum(impact1)) after2 = sum(sum(impact2)) after3 = sum(sum(impact3)) before = sum(sum(source)) relerrl = (afterl - before)/before relerr2 = (after2 — before)/before 161 relerr3 (after3 - before)/before relimpactl = impactl/totalsource relimpact2 = impact2/totalsource relimpact3 = impact3/totalsource ic sum(sum(shape *(-1) crop_impactl crop_impact2 crop_impact3 tcrop_impactl tcrop_impact2 tcrop_impact3 + 1)) (shape * (-1) + 1) (shape * (-1) + 1) (shape * (-1) + 1) sum(sum(crop_impact1)) sum(sum(crop_impact2)) sum(sum(crop_impact3)) .* impactl .* impact2 .* impact3 r1 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impactl) .* crop_impactl ) r2 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact2) .* crop_impact2 ) r3 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact3) .* crop_impact3 ) pestl = pesto * (1 - r1) pest2 = pesto * (1 — r2) pest3 = pesto * (1 - r3) dml = (d1 * pestl)./(1 + (d1 * pestl / d2 )) dm2 = (d1 * pest2)./(1 + (d1 * pest2 / d2 )) dm3 = (d1 * pest3)./(1 + (d1 * pest3 / d2 )) y1_sl = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm1)) % Actual soybean yield (bu/ac) y1_52 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm2)) y1_83 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm3)) spi1_ce111 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sl * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) % Soybean profit per CELL spi1_ce112 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_s2 * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) spi1_cell3 = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_s3 * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) cpi1_cell (-1) + 1) pcost_c * (1 + cp_c)) out of production (shape * * rotpi1_celll rotation rotpi1_ce112 rotpi1_ce113 spi1_celll + cpi1_cell spi1_ce112 + spi1_cell3 + cpi1_cell cpil_cell tpil_farml = sum(sum(rotpi1_celll)) tpil_farm2 = sum(sum(rotpi1_ce112)) tpil_farm3 = sum(sum(rotpil_ce113)) tpil_lsl = 4* tpil_farml tpil_lsz = 4* tpil_farm2 tpil_lsB = 4* tpil_farm3 % Change 162 .* 2.4710439 (dx * dy /10000) % Corn profit given NCH taken .* (y0_c * price_c - % Profit per soybean-corn % profit per rotation per farm % profit for landscape in soybean profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farm_sl = ( (sum(sum(spi1_celll))) (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_sz = ( ( / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_s3 = ( (sum(sum(spil_ce113))) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) % Change in rotation profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farml = (tpil_farml - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm2 (tpil_farm2 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm3 = (tpil_farm3 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm % Change in rotation profit at the landscape scale from baseline sum(sum(spil_ce112))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) change_lsl = (tpil_lsl — tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_ls2 = (tpil_lsZ — tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_ls3 = (tpil_ls3 - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls checkl = change_lsl - change_farml check2 = change_lsZ ~ change_farm2 check3 = change_ls3 - change_farm3 % Output output=[farmingsystem; n; pesto; n_spray; p; reduc; alpha; beta; cp_s; cp’c; ncadist; change_farm_sl; change_farm_sz; change_farm_s3; change_farml; change_farm2; change_farm3;change_lsl; change_ls2; change_lsB]; fprintf(fid,'%12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.4f %12.4f %12.0f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f\n', output); end end %%%%%%%%%% Archipelago %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% for ncadist = 3 % Landscapes with archipelago NCH for p = 1:1:16 if p == 1 cp_s = 0.12 cp c = 0.084 elseif p == 2 Cp 8 = 0.239 cp_c = 0.168 elseif p == 3 cp_s = 0.359 cp_c = 0.252 elseif p == 4 % cp_s = 0.479 cp_c = 0.337 elseif p == 5 cp_s = 0.598 cp_c = 0.421 elseif p == 6 cp_s = 0.718 cp_c = 0.505 elseif p == 7 cpfls = 0.837 cp_c = 0.589 163 reduc=interp1(pp, reduc_data, p) % to p for i=1 elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c elseif p cp_s cp_c end :(n/2) for j=1:(n/2) end end totalsource fsource impactl impact2 impact3 % Balan distributi archip(i,j)=(rand(1)< archip source shape CE on max(0, real(fftshift(ifft2(fK2 real(fftshift(ifft2(fK3 = 8 0.957 0.673 9 1.077 0.757 10 1.196 0.841 11 1.316 0.926 12 1.436 1.010 13 1.555 1.094 14 1.675 1.178 15 1.794 1.262 16 1.914 1.346 pest reduction (%) corresponding (p/100)); archip * dx * dy * alpha*(dx*dy)‘beta archip sum(sum(source)) fft2(source) real(fftshift(ifft2(fK1 .* fsource)))) .* fsource))) .* fsource))) check: total impact must be equal before and after over the landscape afterl = sum(sum(impact1)) after2 after3 before relerrl relerr2 sum(sum(impact2)) sum(sum(impact3)) sum(sum(source)) (afterl - before)/before (after2 - before)/before 164 relerr3 = (after3 - before)/before relimpactl = impactl/totalsource relimpact2 = impact2/totalsource relimpact3 = impact3/totalsource ic = sum(sum(shape *(-1) + 1)) crop_impactl = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* impactl crop_impact2 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* impact2 crop_impact3 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* impact3 tcrop_impactl tcrop_impact2 tcrop_impact3 sum(sum(crop_impact1)) sum(sum(crop_impact2)) sum(sum(crop_impact3)) r1 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impactl) .* crop_impactl ) r2 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact2) .* crop_impact2 ) r3 = min(1, (reduc * ic / tcrop_impact3) .* crop_impact3 ) pestl = pesto * (1 - r1) pest2 = pesto * (1 - r2) pest3 = pesto * (1 - r3) dml = (d1 * pestl)./(1 + (d1 * pestl / d2 )) dm2 = (d1 * pest2)./(1 + (d1 * pest2 / d2 )) /( )) dm3 = (d1 * pest3). 1 + (d1 * pest3 / d2 y1_sl = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (l - dm1)) % Actual soybean yield (bu/ac) y1_s2 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm2)) y1_s3 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* (ymax_s * (1 - dm3)) spil_celll = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sl * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) % Soybean profit per CELL spil_cellz = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_sZ * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) spi1_ce113 = (shape * (-1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y1_s3 * price_s - pcost_s * (1 + cp_s)) * (dx * dy / 10000) cpil_cell = (shape * (—1) + 1) .* 2.4710439 .* (y0_c * price_c - pcost_c * (1 + cp_c)) * (dx * dy /10000) % Corn profit given NCH taken out of production rotpi1_celll rotation rotpi1_ce112 rotpi1_ce113 spil_celll + cpi1_cell % Profit per soybean-corn spi1_ce112 + cpi1_cell spi1_ce113 + cpil_cell tpil_farml sum(sum(rotpi1_celll)) % profit per rotation per farm tpil_farm2 = sum(sum(rotpi1_ce112)) tpil_farm3 = sum(sum(rotpi1_ce113)) tpil_lsl = 4* tpil_farml % profit for landscape tpil_lsZ = 4* tpil_farm2 tpil_lsB = 4* tpil_farm3 % Change in soybean profit at the farm scale from baseline 165 change_farm_sl = ( (sum(sum(spi1_celll))) — (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_sZ = ( (sum(sum(spi1_ce112))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) change_farm_s3 = ( (sum(sum(spi1_ce113))) - (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) ) / (sum(sum(spi0_cell))) % Change in rotation profit at the farm scale from baseline change_farml = (tpil_farml — tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm2 (tpil_farm2 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm change_farm3 - (tpil_farm3 - tpiO_farm) / tpiO_farm % Change in rotation profit at the landscape scale from baseline change_lsl = (tpil_lsl - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_lsz = (tpil_lsz - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls change_ls3 = (tpil_ls3 - tpiO_ls) / tpiO_ls checkl = change_lsl - change_farml check2 = change_ls2 - change_farm2 check3 = change_ls3 — change_farm3 % Output output=[farmingsystem; n; pesto; n_spray; p; reduc; alpha; beta; cp_s; cp_c; ncadist; change_farm_sl; change_farm_sz; change_farm_s3; change_farml; change_farm2; change_farm3;change_lsl; change_lsz; change_ls3]; fprintf(fid,'%12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.0f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.2f %12.4f %12.4f %12.0f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f %12.4f\n', output); end end end 166 Appendix C: Estimated relationship between the pest reduction impact and the proportion of non-crop habitats in the landscape Proportion of reduction in aphid density as compared to the case Aphid density Proportion of non-crop habitats when the proportion of non-crop Japhids/mz)a in landscape habitats in landscape is 0.01b 4600 0.01 O 3400 0.04 0.26 l 533 0.09 0.67 0 0.16 l a Aphid density in wheat at the time of harvest (Julian date 230). Data source: Bianchi and van der Werf, 2003 b Calculated by author. 167 Appendix D: Proportion of change in variable costs of production due to the establishment of non-crop habitats (Lambda) Square # of # of strips strips proportion coef of Lambda Lambda Lambda Lambda prop_ in outside # of of total machinery (organic (conv (organic (conv NCH NCH NCH turns field time cost com) com) soy) soy) 0 0 400 399 0.15 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 40 360 439 0.17 1.02 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.02 57 343 456 0.17 1.02 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.03 69 331 468 0.18 1.03 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.04 80 320 479 0.18 1.03 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.05 89 31 1 488 0.18 1.03 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.06 98 302 497 0.19 1.04 0.01 -0.01 0.01 0.00 0.07 106 294 505 0.19 1.04 0.00 -0.01 0.01 0.00 0.08 1 13 287 512 0.19 1.04 0.00 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.09 120 280 519 0.20 1.05 0.00 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.1 126 274 525 0.20 1.05 0.00 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.1 1 133 267 532 0.20 1.05 0.00 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.12 139 261 538 0.20 1.05 0.00 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.13 144 256 543 0.20 1.05 0.00 -0.02 0.01 -0.01 0.14 150 250 549 0.21 1.06 0.00 -0.02 0.01 -0.01 0.15 155 245 554 0.21 1.06 0.00 -0.02 0.01 -0.02 0.16 160 240 559 0.21 1.06 0.00 -0.02 0.01 -0.02 168 Appendix D (cont’d): Proportion of change in variable costs of production due to the establishment of non-crop habitats (Lambda) Strip # of # of strips strips proportion coef of Lambda Lambda Lambda Lambda prop_ in outside # of of total machinery (organic (conv (organic (conv NCH NCH NCH turns field time cost comL corn) sgy) soy) 0 0 400 399 0.15 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 4 396 395 0.15 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 8 392 391 0.15 1 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.00 0.03 12 388 387 0.15 1 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.04 16 384 383 0.14 0.99 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.05 20 380 379 0.14 0.99 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.06 24 376 375 0.14 0.99 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.07 28 372 371 0.14 0.99 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.08 32 368 367 0.14 0.99 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 0.09 36 364 363 0.14 0.99 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 0.1 40 360 359 0.13 0.98 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.02 0.1 l 44 356 355 0.13 0.98 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.02 0.12 48 352 351 0.13 0.98 -0.03 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 0.13 52 348 347 0.13 0.98 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.03 0.14 56 344 343 0.13 0.98 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.03 0.15 60 340 339 0.13 0.98 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.03 0.16 64 336 335 0.13 0.98 -0.03 -0.03 -0.04 -0.03 169 _ Appendix D (cont’d): Proportion of change in variable costs of production due to the establishment of non-crop habitats (Lambda) Archipelago proportion coef of Lambda Lambda Lambda prop_ number of Number of total machinery (organic (conv (organic Lambda NC H NCH cells of tums field time cost com) com) soy) Aconv soy) 0 0 399 0.15 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 1600 1999 0.75 1.60 0.24 0.08 0.37 0.12 0.02 3200 3599 1.35 2.20 0.47 0.17 0.75 0.24 0.03 4800 5199 1.95 2.80 0.71 0.25 1.12 0.36 0.04 6400 6799 2.56 3.41 0.95 0.34 1.50 0.48 0.05 8000 8399 3.16 4.01 1.19 0.42 1.87 0.60 0.06 9600 9999 3.76 4.61 1.42 0.50 2.24 0.72 0.07 11200 11599 4.36 5.21 1.66 0.59 2.62 0.84 0.08 12800 13199 4.96 5.81 1.90 0.67 2.99 0.96 0.09 14400 14799 5.56 6.41 2.13 0.76 3.37 1.08 0.1 16000 16399 6.17 7.02 2.37 0.84 3.74 1.20 0.1 1 17600 17999 6.77 7.62 2.61 0.93 4.12 1.32 0.12 19200 19599 7.37 8.22 2.85 1.01 4.49 1.44 0.13 20800 21199 7.97 8.82 3.08 1.09 4.86 1.56 0.14 22400 22799 8.57 9.42 3.32 1.18 5 .24 1.67 0.15 24000 24399 9.17 10.02 3.56 1.26 5.61 1.79 0.16 25600 25999 9.77 10.62 3.79 1.35 5.99 1.91 170 Appendix E: Production costs by farming system and crop Soybean Proportion of Machinery (repair, Seed machinery cost in Proportion of fuel and hire) ($/ha) A8/ha) VC (S/ha) VC seed cost in VC Organic 162.5 47.5 260 0.63 0.18 Conv 52.5 47.5 260 0.20 0.18 Corn Proportion of Machinery (repair, Seed machinery cost in Proportion of fuel and hire) ($/ha) (S/ha) VC (s/th VC seed cost in VC Organic 187.5 75 472.5 0.40 O. 16 Conv 70 87.5 490 0.14 0.18 Source: UIUC, 2003. 171 uTTTTTITTTTTTIT):