.Ilh. cowl . ‘ "1 -., 5'» l". . "n .1, ‘34.. , “c "at!" “5.x 1 . ‘5 a)»: g x _ 1. xi ,. 1; .gt‘fiarf : 1;“ a ’13 3" €335 um}: 3%: x 'A b ‘1")? . 9 m “ 5‘42 . . 3‘9 ‘ .. . ”fit: - 2.35:1? .15 2“ :1» P 1‘ . 633$“ ‘ . m4- , ‘4-” fé‘vfifl ,. p t.- s L . k x? Liza .L ,’ 150? LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS presented by Na Yang has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the PhD. degree in Economics QWIM' Major Pfldfe'ssror’s Sigjature Arr/5M; 3% Date MSU is an affirmative-action. equal-opportunity employer PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DAIEDUE DATEDUE DATEDUE 6/07 p:/ClRC/DateDue.indd-p.1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS By NA YANG A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2008 ABSTRACT THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS By NA YANG Chapter 1: The logarithmical form of the trade volume does not acconnnodate the situation of zero trade l’)etween certain country pairs. This paper starts with a tl'ieoretical framework of hetm'ogeneous firms to show the true property of zero trade: “actual" instead of “potential” and proposes a two-part model framework to deal with zero trade problems. The marginal effect derived from the non-linear combination of the two parts significantly corrects the bias generated by estimating the gravity model using conventional methods. Chapter 2 (with Isao Kamata): In this paper we examine how factor proportions determine the extensive margin of trade. Different from the existing research that only analyzes the country-level export pattern in varieties, we explore the problem at a disaggregate industry level. A quasi—Heckscher-Ohlin prediction for export varieties emerges from the model: countries export more varieties in the industries that more intensively use their abundant resources as input factors. The model also delivers important implications of opening autarky to trade: besides commonly-accepted facts of larger trade volume for each exporting firm, there is also a stronger selection of firms into the export market in comparative advantage industries. Chapter 3: In this paper we explore the linkage between population health and inward FDI in a cross-country setting. A semi-IV framework proposed by Frankel and Romer (1999) is used to account for the endogeneity of FDI. We estimate FDI with exogenous geographical variables and also investigate the effect of F DI- indueed openness on health conditions. To my parents iii ACI\'NO\-’\"LEDGEl\-IENTS I would like to acknowledge many people for helping me during my doctm‘al work. First and foremost, I thank my advisor. Steven Matusz. for his generous time and ('ton'nnitment. Throughout my doctoral study he encouraged me to develop independent thinking and research skills. I have greatly benefited from his valuable feedback on this thesis and everything else I have written. I would also like to thank all the members in my (‘lissertation conunittee, Dr. Carl Davidson. Dr. Susan 21111, Dr. Joseph Gardiner and Dr. Jun-Koo Kang. for their guidance and mentorship. I thank the Department of Economics for the financial support of my graduate study all the way through thus making it possible for me to focus on my research. I particularly thank Zhehui Luo and Dr. Joseph Gardiner. for giving me the. opportunity to work 011 their projects so that I was extensixv'ely exposed to the empirical study arena and for sharing with me their insights constantly, not only on the e(-.()iionietrics problems, but also on life. which helped me to grow as an individual. I thank Dr. J. Roy Black, to hire me as his Research Assistant when I was just a first year PhD student and knew only the basics of STATA. Dr. Jun- Koo Kang generously provided me the Japanese firm-level data he purchased and loaned me the only copy of the disk he had. I also owe a lot to Professor Amsler for treating me not only as a student and her 'I‘eaching Assistant. but also as a friend; I am forever indebted to her encoiiragement when I was very frustrated with my research. I extend many thanks to my colleagues and friends, especially my coauthor. Isao Kamata, and the friends from Lansing Chinese Christian Fellmvship. I thank my parents because they have been a constant source of love, support and encouragement. I thank them for their faith in me and allowing me to be as ambitious as I wanted. And I give thanks to the LORD, for he is good: for his mercy endureth for ever. i v TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................ vi LIST OF FIGURES .............................................................................. viii Chapter 1 Treatment of Zero Trade Volume and Re-estimation of Gravity Equation: an Analysis with Two-Part Model 1. Introduction ................................................................................. 1 2. Cross-Country Trade Pattern ............................................................. 4 3. The model ................................................................................... 6 4. Choice between Sample-Selection Model and Two-Part Model? ....................... 11 5. Specifications of the two-part model ................................................... 14 6. Estimation result .......................................................................... 19 7. Conclusion ................................................................................. 23 Chapter 2 Explaining Export Varieties: the Unexplored Role of Comparative Advantage I. Introduction ............................................................................... 25 2. The model ................................................................................. 26 3. The Data ................................................................................... 35 4. Empirical test .............................................................................. 37 5. Conclusion ................................................................................. 40 Chapter 3 Globalized but Unhealthy? A Feedback on Population Health from FDI 1. Introduction ............................................................................... 42 2. How does FDI affect health ............................................................. 44 3. Data and specifications .................................................................. 50 4. Empirical analysis ........................................................................ 55 5. Conclusion ................................................................................. 57 APPENDICES Appendix A .................................................................................... 64 AppendixB ..................................................................................... 68 BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................... 105 LIST OF TABLES Table 1: World International Trade and Production ......................................... 5 Table 2: Relationship between Composition of Trade & Country Characteristics, Year 2000 ................................................................................................ 6 Table 3: List of Countries ...................................................................... 74 Table 4: Summary Statistics .................................................................... 75 Table 5: Estimation of Gravity Equations by Conventional Methods .................... 76 Table 6: Estimation Result: 2-part Model without Sampling Weight ..................... 77 Table 7: Estimation Result: 2-part Model with Sampling Weight ........................ 78 Table 8: Marginal Effect Derived from Other Methods .................................... 79 Table 9: Marginal Effect of Iog(distance) and RTA on Iog(trade volume) (with Weight Factor .............................................................................................. 80 Table 10: Marginal Effect of Iog(distance) and RTA on Iog(trade volume) (without Weight Factor .................................................................................... 8] Table 11: Vuong(1989)’s Test for Model Selection ......................................... 82 Table 12: US. Import and Varieties in 1990 ................................................. 83 Table 13: Country List (as of 1990, 115 countries) .......................................... 84 Table 14: Factor Abundance of Countries: Skilled Labor to Unskilled Labor ........... 85 I Table 15: Input Factor Intensity of Industries: Skilled-labor to Unskilled Labor ........ 86 Table 16: List of Countries in Aggregate North and South ................................. 87 Table 17: Skilled-to-Unskilled Labor Ratios of North and South .......................... 88 Table 18: Regressions for Aggregate North and South ...................................... 89 Table 19: Pooled Regression for Individual Exporters ....................................... 90 Table 20: Summary Statistics ................................................................... 96 vi Table 21: Countries List ......................................................................... 97 Table 22: Predicting FDI: Positive Volume Only ............................................ 98 Table 23: Predicting FDI: Using Two-part Model Approach .............................. 99 Table 24: Life Expectancy (Level) and FDI Ratio (log), Year 2002 ..................... 100 Table 25: Life Expectancy (log) and FDI Ratio (log) , Year 2002 ........................ 101 Table 26: Mortality (level) and FDI ratio (log), Year 2002 ............................... 102 Table 27: Life Expectancy (level) and FDI Ratio (log), Year 2002, With Two-part Model Including All 170 Countries ........................................................... 103 Table 28: Mortality (level) and FDI Ratio(log), Year 2002, 170 Countries Sample...104 vii LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1: Cross—Country Distribution of Trade .............................................. 71 Figure 2: Geographical Distribution of RTAs (in force or under negotiation) .......... 72 Figure 3: Geographical Distribution of RTAs as of year 2000 ............................ 73 Figure 4: Number of Exporters to the US. in Each Manufacturing Industry ............ 90 Figure 5: Scatterplot of Number of Exporters v.5. Industry Skilled-labor Intensity (U.S. Manufacturing Imports in 1990) ................................................................ 91 Figure 6: Scatterplot of Number of Varieties v.s. Industry Skilled—labor Intensity (U.S. Manufacturing Imports in 1990) ................................................................ 92 Figure 7: Individual Exporter Regression: Scatterplot of Slope Coefficient v.s. Abundance of the Country ....................................................................... 93 Figure 8: Exporter’s Relative Factor Abundance, Industry Factor Intensity, and Number of Varieties in US. Manufacturing Imports in 1990 (1): Selected Skilled Labor- abundant Countries (relative to unskilled) ..................................................... 94 Figure 9: Exporter’s Relative Factor Abundance, Industry Factor Intensity, and Number of Varieties in US. Manufacturing Imports in 1990 (2): Selected Unskilled Labor- abundant Countries (relative to unskilled) ..................................................... 95 viii Chapter 1: Treatment of Zero Trade Volume and Re—estimation of Gravity Equation: Analysis Using Two-Part Models 1. Introduction The gravity model has a long history in the trade literature. The original gravity model assumes the goods produced at an origin and attracted to a destina- tion are proportional to the productions of the two locations, and the friction term adds the impedance of making travels of various durations or distances. Tinber— gen(1962) was the first to use gravity model for estimation of bilateral trade flows, by substituting the production levels with two countries" GDPs and using trade resistance for the friction term. Over time, his approach has been vastly cited and furnished with better empirical estimation teclmiques and used to explain other aspects of international trade than the trade volume only. For example, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) showed that the gravity model should be augmented with exporter and importer fixed effects because the traditional one does not take the multiple resistance terms into account. In his seminal paper, Krugman formalized the role played by the geographical proximity in the regionalization process. In Frankel and Romer (1999), they showed that regionalization could be explained by geographical proximity and preferential trade agreements, with country sizes being constant. Moreover, Rauch (1999) showed that differentiated products could exhibit. stronger geographical proximity effects than homogeneous products within a gravity model structure. Though the gravity model has been widely recognized for its empirical success in predicting the trade volume and estimating the effects of the factors that impede bilateral trade, it initially did not. have a strong theoretical background. 1Recently there has been an increasing trend to use both the traditional and new trade theories to derive the gravity model. For instance, Deardorff (1995) derived it from a traditional Hechscher—Ohlin perspective while Eaton and Kortum (1997) used a Ricardian framework. Additionally. Helpman(1987) used both monopolistic competition model and gravity equation for an analysis and argued that the close of fit. of the gravity model of trade variable could serve as supportive empirical evidence for the 111011<)1i)()listi(- competion model. For empirics. Learner(1974) used both the gravity equation and the Heckscher- Ohlin model to motivate the explanatory variables in a regression analysis of the trade flows. Notably in Helpman(1987). he. applied his test to data on trade of the OECD countries, which yielded supportive evidence to the monopolistic competition model. Hummels and Levinsohn (1995) expanded the test to a much wider variety of countries, using different data and different estimation methods to test whether the data still supports the theory.2 All in all, these studies have improved our 1.111derstanding of the gravity equa- tion as a tool to model and analyze bilateral trade. But what is common in the existing research is that the. analysis of gravity model was only applied on sample countries that have positive trade flows between them. However, a direct result. of discarding zero trade volumes could result in biased estimates. In this paper we developed a heterogeneous firm model following Melitz (2003) then used the theo- retical predictions to show how to amend the gravity model to deal with zero trade flows. The heterogeneity is introduced in a similar way to Melitz (2003): firms face uncertainty about their future productivities: the entry fees for both producing for the domestic market and exporting to foreign markets are costly and irreversible. The model delivers a set of implications for export probability and export volume. Similar to the l\"Ielitz's model, this paper allows the fact that none of the firms in one. country has such productivity level that they can break even when they enter any other foreign market. As a result, the model incorporates the likelihood of zero volume of trade l’)etween some country pairs as well as positive trade volume in one direction from country ’1'. to country j, but zero trade flow from country j to country 2. For predicted positive two-way trade, the model generates a gravity equation in which the size of trade flow is proportional to the sizes of the partners, but dampened by bilateral barriers. Using various sources, I then assembled a dataset on bilateral trade and gravity measures for all the countries. The availability of the gravity measures makes it possible for us to accurately construct gravity measures for both country samples with zero trades and positive trade volumes. Along the lines of research on gravity equations. the paper fundamentally dif- fers from the existing research in two dimensions. Theoretically, it uses Melitz(2003) ”s heterogeneous firm model to derive the gravity equation for both the export probability and volume besides the established Hechscher—Ohlin structure and tra- ditional monopolistic competition model. With the heterogeneous firm setting, we rationalized the true feature of zero trade, which is significant suggesting the proper handling of zeros. The generalization of the gravity model accounts for the asymmetries between the volume of exports from 2' to j and the trade volume from j to 2'. But different from Helpman, Melitz and Rubinstein (2006), the firm-level l’ieterogeneity term does not enter our estimation specification on the country lev 31. Empirically, we propose a two-part model, which has been intensively used in other fields so that we can better address the problem of zero trade and correct the po- tential bias generated by the conventional estimation methods. We also explained how to compute the correct marginal effects of covariates on actual outcomes with different distributional specifications. A Vuong’s test. is used to sort. out the best fit of the model for actual trade data. In a. recent paper, Helpman et al. (2006) proposed a technique similar to sample selection model. We argue that two part model is more appropriate than sample selection in handling the problem of zero trade based on the fact that trade values are actual instead of potential. In two papers by \Yesterlnnd and \Vilhelmsson (2006), Silva and Tenreyro (2000), they proposed a Poisson maximum likelihood estimator(Pl\ILE). Although the PLME outperforms conventional OLS by removing the need to linearize the model, it makes strong assumptions on count data regression that might be inapplicable when dealing with continuous trade volume. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the cross country trade pattern. In section 3 we use. the model of heterogeneous firm to clarify the true. property of zero trade— actual instead of potential outcomes, and it is addressed that there is no selection bias problem when modeling the actual trade. outcomes. Section 4 studies the. econometric problems raised by conventional methods and section 5 proposes two-part estimation techniques with different sets of parametric distributions. We also explain how to compute the correct marginal effects for covariatesein this paper, distance and regional trade agreement. Addi- tionally. a Vuong test is used for model selection. Section 6 provides the informa- tion of data and estimation results. The results are. compared with those. generated by OLS, adjusted OLS and non—linear least squares estimations. Section 6 contains concluding remarks. 2. Cross-country trade pattern Since 19908, international transactions are playing an increasingly important role in world trade. Table 1 shows the world GDP and world export growth path from 1982 to 2001. The volume of export approximately constitutes around 20% of total world GDP. and grows at a steady rate in levels. Next we show the composition of country—pairs according to their trade sta- tus in figure 1 - country-pairs with two-way trade. one-way trade and no trade 1982 1990 1996 2001 World GDP (in billion dollars) 11.758 22,610 29,024 31,900 W'orld export (in billion dollars) 2.247 4.261 6,523 7,430 World export as 0/0 of GDP 19 19 22 23 Table 1: World International Trade and Production at all. Years 1980-1997 are considered. From 1980-1997, the country pairs that are involved in either bilateral or unilateral trade constitute around 3070—5001, of all possible country pairs.3However. the proportion of one way trade relationships stays at a fairly constant level of 10% along the early 90s. These years also wit- nessed an increasing share of country pairs with positive two-way trade. Generally, the gravity approach suggests that trade volume is a function of trading partners’ sizes and trade barriers. _ The GDPs are usually used to reflect the sizes of exporters and importers. The importer’s market size. represents the market demand for bilateral trade, and exporter’s size reflects the potential com- modity supply. Geographic distance is usually used as the term of resistance, along with other binary variables to proxy other aspects of economics integration factor or trade barrier factor. Using Feenstra(1995)’s trade dataset for year 2000 and country-pair characteristics, in Table 2 we show the correlations between the possibility to trade and gravity variables. Particularly, the average distance among the group of country pairs that do not have any trade is much bigger than country pairs that. have positive trade. The average GDP products are also substantially larger for countries with positive trade. In fact, the GDP products for country pairs with two way trade are almost. as twice as that of country pairs with one way trade. and almost 20 times of the products for countries with zero trade. Two-way trade country pairs include larger proportion of both countries affiliated with the same regional trade agreement compared with one-way trade and zero trade. However, the benefit of sharing the common language is not quite clear, this could stem from the fact, of the large two— way one-way zero trade trade trade Mean distance(in kilometers) 6959 8027 8495.82 (X with common language 12.10 12.82 17.96 (7t with connnon border 2.95 0.69 1.14 GDP products(in e+19 US $) 17400 8220 922 (it of landlocked exporters 13.15 15.58 21.05 (7(. of landlocked importers 13.15 18.22 20.87 mean of # of exporter major cities 21.10 22.92 23.85 mean of # of importer major cities 21.05 23.69 23.85 Ct of country pairs with common RTA 7.25 4.14 6.42 Number of country pairs 8,940 1.739 25,611 ft of all country pairs 24.63 4.79 70.57 Table 2: Relationship between composition of trade and country characteristics, year 2000 economic variation among Ei‘iglish—speaking countries. In summary, the evidence presented in the previous tables and figure 1 suggest that size and geography are very important factors to explain the existence of trade and the. level of export volumes. 3. The model The model of trade with l’ieterogeneous firms is built 111) based on Melitz (2003)4 The world is comprised of J countries, j=1,2 ....... .l. ()n the demand side. the preferences of a. representative consumer are given by a standard C.E.S. utility function over consumption of a continuum of goods x (n varieties) indexed by l. The varieties of x are imperfect substitutes. where (7 = 1/ (1 — p) > 1 indexes the substitution pattern between varieties of x. Country j‘s utility is expressed as: ,n, 1 UJ- = [/Jrawdzjfi (1.1) 0 \Vitli c(.)nsumers maximizing their utilitities subject to the budget constraints, it. leads to the demand of variety I in country j: 6 .rJ-(l) = riff—115(1)“ (1.2) n 1 where Y]- is the total income of countryj and Pj = [f p(1)1—0(11]1——? denotes 0 the aggregate price index; pj is the price of variety 1 in country j. For production, labor is the only factor of production and is inelastically supplied in a market. The unit price of labor in country j is j‘)arameterized at cj. There is a large pool of 1,)ropective entrants into the industry. The production of (‘lifferentiated good .1‘ is characterized by monopolistic com- petition. All the potential entrants are the same ex ante. To enter the market, firms in country j need to incur a sunk cost fncj so that they can draw their productivities (,3 from a distribution C(99). Once the firm knows its productivity, it needs to choose to produce or exit. Successful entrants could make nonnegative profit. with high enough productivity; however, if the productivity draw is below a, cutoff level. it is best. off exiting at. once. The productivity t;(l) for firm to produce variety I is drawn from a Pareto distribution with the range of [ 1,9113ij and shape parameter [3.5 The total cost for production of variety 1 at (1 quantity is comjn‘ised of two parts: the variable cost and fixed cost ( f D units of labor). qc- 53(7) + chj (1.3) In a monopolistic competition characterized economy, the pricing rule of a profit-maximizing firm with efficiency level to is: 15(1) = —’— (1.1) For a given firm, we could simply express the profit of the firm (with product I) from domestic sale as: c- ,. 7 1—0 win=e—pn-e—e—) —hx- (Le J J WUlpj J The same derivation applies to the profit from trade, where Tj, is the “melting iceberg" cost which is bigger than one; equally speaking le- units of goods need to be shipped in order for one unit to arrive. Thus the profit for the firm (with product I) from country j to export to cmmtry i is: man=o—«ngg§%§fica—tmj (Le f ji is the units of labor needed as fixed cost wl‘ien firms produce at country j and export to country i, and it is larger than f D, which is needed to produce for domestic market. Evidently with this assumption, this profit is positive for sales in the domestic markets, because fji is bigger than f D- It also follows that only a proportion of country j’s firms could export to country i. The free entry condition for firms from country j implies: fer = (1“ G(s3}))fgh(ej)+(1- Gwzillfji‘jh(WEfl) (1-7) and similarly for firms from country 2', feCi = (1‘ affillfC—ihbifl + (1 — C(QLJUfijCihf‘PLJ‘) (1-8) ~‘ ,,, , >1: where h.(;,9*) = ( YE; ))U—1—1 and 99:17 is the benchmark productivity needed for exporting to happen from country j to country i. Similarly, 99:1}. is for export from country i to country j. (,9: identifies the lowest productivity level to produce at home. Given these conditions. we can obtain the following: Lemma 1: @2131 " lei—”>07 —=91 (1.9) * f 99.171? fji .—1 (‘1' 01,- 9”? f (Ci) Yz‘ 2 Proof: See appendix A By substituting (1.9) and (1.10) into (1.7) and (1.8), it leads to a system of equations with two unknowns (,9: and (,9; : . 99L k /.9 :19 (K —1)(:}.> +fJ.9(K—1)(Q:.,,2> (1.11) fe(i: f0.“ A — 1)(:§)k +fsz-i(K _ 1)(¢::51)k (1.12) where K = 11%;. Solving the system yields: 6 k , _. (If—1w " (.9) "= L (1.13) f f2?! f+ 13277275? From equation (1.8) and (1.12). the export. productivity cutoff is determined by : * f__’-_] 7.0— 1 010(K—1)9‘;[: -1 Y’rlj: f (P ) ( 792 j f+ f‘flT—fi—T where {21 and 92 are given by equations (1.9) and (1.10). which only consist (1.14) of exogenous variables. Define the ratio of cutoff productivity to export. and the highest productivity 1" V’Hi as: Dji = ‘ (1.15) The. probability for country j to export to i is determined by prob(DJ-,j < 1). in another word. under the circumstances that the cutoff point to export (from j to i) is bigger than 99;, the bilateral trade volume equals zero. The proportion of the firms that could be involved in exporting activities in a given country is determined by function: A((5,j. (ij. 60-): where 9k (k = i,j) is country-specific characteristics and 61-]- is bilateral gravity covariates. From equations (1.9)—(1.10), the term (.931. and 93:0- export productivity cutoffs are also determined accordingly. When trade is possible for two countries, or at least for trade in one direction, the level of trade would be: 0.7.. J 1’ Nit- Tji =( (2”‘l(IG(-.a) (1-16) \' 491(- 991' i This function is again a function of two countries’ variables and bilateral gravity covariates, which we. will generalize to the function TM 1‘, 63-, (SI-j). For empirical fran'iework. equations (1.15) and (1.16) are related to export. probability and export volume separately for (,:ross-l:)or(ler transactions from coun- try j to 1'. Both the probability to trade and trade volume between two countries could be decomposed into three components as Helpman, Melitz and Rubinstein (2006) showed: one that depends on importer characteristics. one that depends on exporter characteristics, and a. third that depends on the country pair characteris- 10 tics. The decompositition resembles Anderson and van W incoop (2003)”s gravity equation that embodies all three sets of variables. But unlike Helpman, l\1‘Ielitz and Rubinstein, we do not include the additional term that controls sample selection bias and proportion of the exporters. Instead. we address the question using a two- part model. The distinction between the sample selection model and the two part model is discussed in section 4.2. Other than model selection due to the property of zero trade. empirically. the two part model also outperforms sample selection because the downward bias for the coefficients of the covariates could arise from the high colinearity between the inverse-Mills ratio and the countries’ covariates if sample sele("tion is used. 4. Choice between sample selection model and two-part model The two-part model has been used intensively in the field of health economics to deal with data that. includes a large fraction of zero values, such as the cigarette demand, hospital utilization and health insurance coverage. The sample selection model is often misapplied to the corner solution problem. thus deriving the wrong marginal effect as their main interest. This debate on the choice over Heckman sample selection model and two part model (hereafter, 2PM) went back to the famous “cake debate” of the 19803. Jones in Handbook of Health Econon‘iics documented an excellent history of the “cake debate”The sample selection model has dominated much of the literature in mi- croeconomics and the Heckit estimation procedure is routinely adopted to analyze the problems involving censoring and selection bias. The earlier comparisons are mostly based on theoretical issues 6and the recent investigations have. turned to Monte. Carlo simulation experiments7. There seems to be. a general 111isunder- standing of the terms “censored” and “selected" samples, especially when applied to the two-part model setting. As \Vooldridge (2002) points out. a second kind of application of censored regressirm models appears more often in econometrics, 11 and tmfortunately. is where the label “censored regression” is the least appropri- ate. Though in many situations the problems we are trying to solve arise from an optimization problem and the true feature is corner solution. the name “censored models" appears to be more entrenched. Besides V‘Vooldridge (2002), Dovr and Norton (2003) also clearly addressed several issues regarding the merits and usage of the Heckit and two-part model when applied to data with a large chunk of zero values. \Vhen choosing between the two models, we need to first. distinguish between potential values and actual values. Both methods are used when dealing with continuous outcome variables with a large portion of zeros. But the choice over the two models depends 1_)rimarily on the distinction between actual value and potential value. \Vhen dealing with trade volume, an actual zero volume is observable, whereas positive volumes generally exhibits a skewed-to—tlie-right continuous distribution. For example, in a specified period patients either have zero health expense or a positive expense, but not negative expenditure; and in the same fashion the zero trade values in our heterogeneous firm model are corner solutions ——-t,.rue zeros instead of missing values, therefore we do not have a sample selection issue to address. In contrast, the potential outcome is a latent variable that could not be fully observed. Zeros do not represent the fact that true values should be zero. In labor economics, observations without positive wage outcomes do not. imply that these people would work for zero wages; instead these wages are non—observable. In the same way. potential expenditures that have never occurred would not affect the health care budget. Dow and Norton (2003) also gave an example of this type. For a person with zero health expenditure, it does not mean his potential expenditure would be zero if he had been examined by a doctor and indeed had 12 sought any health care. The Heckit model would work better in this situation because the observed working people are likely to be different. from the unobserved non—working people. From our theoretical derivation of the last section, we are able to show that the true feature of zero trades here is indeed corner solutions for country pairs because countries choose not. to trade when all the firms in their counties have productivities below the necessary benchmark. Therefore two-part modeling is more appropriate when zeros are the actual observed trade volume between two countries and we are interested in the determinants of the actual trade. In mathematical terms, both models consist. of two equations. For Heckit model, the first equation models the probability of having a positive value (se- lection equation), and the second equation expresses the mean trade volume in the sub—population with the positive trade volume (the conditional equation), the conditional equation usually takes the form of: E(yly > 0, X) 2 X232 + 71/\(X1;31) (1.17) where /\(X1,r31) is the inverse-Mills ratio term under the assumption of normality of latent variable that denotes the potential trade volume. However, in the two part model, the second equation does not include this term due to the nature of the zeros, which makes it simply: E(y|y > 0, X) 2 X233 (1.18) Therefore, when sample selection is inappropriately invoked for actual values. 0 {'32 will only equate ,8; under special case where there is no selection bias(71 = 0). The two part model should not be confused with standard Tobit model because the two part model allow the hurdle decision (part one) to be separate from the 13 level decision (part. two). Some studies that followed the practice of standard Tobit to estimate gravity equation with zero flows include Rose (2004). Soloaga and \Vinters (2001) and Anderson and l\.lar('touiller (2002). r 0. Specifications of the two-part model Two-part model is sometimes mentioned in other fields in alternative ways— two-tier model or hurdle model. Different from sample selection8, the property of latent variable. is actual instead of potential. Parametrically, we model the first part in the following specificationsprobit and logit. For the distribution of the error term in the second part, we will use lognormal and exponential distributiong. The set up and the merits of the models are discussed below. A Vuong’s test is used at the end of section 5 for model selection. 5.1 Lognormal Distrilimtion The estimation procedure works as follows. We define the dummy variable 10, otherwise from our trade theory as Di, therefore Di means two countries trade no trade exists. In the second level equations, we use Ti for observation ‘2'. (a unique country pair)‘s trade volume. I.Probit and Lognormal: When part one is probit and second part is lognormal, two equations take the f(i)llowing forms: I I , Pa), = 1|X1,-) = magi/31 + 51 > 0) = (X1,:x31) (1.19) I E(T,:|D, = 1, X”) = exp(X2,I-;32 + 0.502) (1.20) 14 where the error terms follow the distrilmtions: €1~N(0, 1), and 111(52) ~ N(0, 02) The unconditional expected value would be: , _ . r . y! _ _ r/ E(Til.\1,‘..\2;) = E(T1lDi = 1,}121') P1‘(DZ' = 1'21“) 2 CXl’b’x‘2).v"32+0-002)(D(AM531) (1.21) The log-likelihood function will change accordingly to I 111 Ti — Xog-HQ 0' I (71(Tl') =111((X11-:31))+ln((.t)( )) — 1110le (1.22) and marginal effect of variable .rk is: 013(3) (9:121C I I I I : (X1.l-131);32k exp(X2,-;32 + 0.502) + @(Xlil31)131kexp(X2z-/32 + 0.502) (1.23) For estimation. when we use total trade volume for level of Ti and for example, .rk is the log form of distance. the elasticity of distance 011 trade volume is: 0E(ln trade) I I I = <1) X 43 13 .. X #3 )3 . X )3 1.24 0(lndistance) ( 1" 1) 2k +6“ 11* 1) 1A( 21 2) f ) The marginal effect of Regional Trade Agreement would take a similar form to average treatment effect: r/ I, _ I . 'I :- 2 fl / exp(.X2’-132 + 0.:102)(X1’-131)|RTA:1 — mph/31213132 + 0.00 )(.X1,i,131)|RTA:0 (1.25) 11. Logit and Lognormal Similarly, we can also compute the 1.1nconditional expected value when part one is legit and second part. is lognormal, I , ,I exp X 4'3 E(T,'|.X1.Ij. XQI) = GXI')(A22-5132 + 0.502) (I 1’ 1) (1.26) exp(.X'17.,z31) + 1 And the log-likelihood function is: (v' a ) 1 T X' 3 ex) . 11 .- — -:. ln(Ti) : In( I ‘I 1" 1 )+ ln(cb( l 2" 2)) — lnaTi (1.27) exp(XlI-f31) + 1 a and marginal effect of ln(distance) would become: ’ . exp(X1l-_x31) I (exp(X1_l.)31) + 1)2 I , I ex1)(X1_i,:'31) + 1 I I 1321. exp ( X2]: :32 +0502 ) + 1311., exr)(X2.,3132 +0.50?) (1.28) It can be shown that the elasticity of distance on trade is: (X' 3 ) (r' 3 ) exp ,7)" 1 / exp 1 31’ 1 , r/ I 1,1 (5211: + I _1? 21131114912132) (L29) 9Xp(X1i/31) + 1 (GXP(X11'(31) + 1) while the effect of RTA 011 trade is: (Y' 3 > I V 9 exp .4) 1 (¥X})(1Y2?-1’32 + 0.50“) I if iRTAZI_ ex1;)(X1i/31) + 1 (X' 3 ) I , exp 1 e.rp(X2,iI32 + 0.502) 1’ 1 lRTAzO (1.30) I , (axr)(X1i;}1) + 1 For the standard gravity estimation, which uses positive trade volumes only, the marginal effect of distance is 1321., which would be a biased result if we want. to know the true effect of distance on the level of trade. What we are interested in 16 HE (111 trade) should be 0E (1n trade trade>0) L ' ' 8(111 distance 8(ln distance) ) instead of . In another word, we need to investigate the effect of the barriers on overall trade for all countries, not. just the sub-sample of positive trades. For both sets of models (probit. and lognormal, logit and lognormal), it can be shown that I). affects E (T,) in three ways: through its effect in the hurdle equation, captured in ,[31 ; through its direct effect in the conditional equation (captured in 1'32); and through the density function of equation I eXp(X1,'(31) I (expuumal)? The two part model is different from sample selection in that it does not I I I I one (oh-‘11,)? 1) 111 model one and 111 model 2). include an inverse-l\eIills—ratio part due to the zero trade property, therefore there is also efficiency gain in 2PM because inverse-Mills ratio term usually generates multicollinearity problem. When dependant variables are. actual values and sample selection is mistakenly used, the nus-specification is analogous to adding a single higher order term of X1 in the second equation. 5.2 Exponential distribution: Another leading case for functional forms that ensure a positive value for the second part is exponential function. In that case, our second part’s function would take the form of: I E(T,:IX2,:. Ti, > 0) = 0XP(X2;/‘32) A commonly used parameterization is to define the probability density func- tion (pdf) of an exponential distribution as: 1 ‘s f(.r) : Xexp(—§) if .r >2 0 17 = 0 if .‘I‘ < (l where A > 0 is a parameter of the distribution. The exponential distribution is used to model Poisson process, in which situation an object initially in state A can change to state B with constant probability per unit time A. The exponen- tial distribution may be also viewed as a continuous counterpart. of the geometric distrilmtion that describes the number of Bernoulli trials necessary for a discrete process to change state. A detailed description of the derivations of log likelihood functions and marginal effects are discussed in Appendix A2. 5.3 Vuong’s test for model selection: In this section, we invoke Vuong (1989)”8 test. to select from the four sets of modelslland choose one that is the closest to the true trade data generating pro- cess. The models are considered non-nested if neither models can be represented as a special case of the other. Models with different non-nested distributions and models with different non—nested functional forms for the conditional mean are called strictly non-nested. The formal definition is given in Vuong (1987) and Pe- saran (1987). In the econometrics literature, starting from Cox (1961, 1962a), the hypothesis testing is performed in a non-standard framework. A brief review is given in Davidson and MacKinnon (1993). Mizon and Richard (1986) proposed the encompassing principle, which leads to a quite general framework for testing one model against the other. VVooldridge (1990b) derived encompassing tests for the conditional mean in nonlinear regression models with heteroskedasticity. In this paper, we follow Vuong (1989) for model selection by discriminating between models on the basis of their distance from the true data—generating process, where distance is measured using the Kulback-Liebler information criterion. The follow- ing statistic is proposed: 18 TI '7 )- (1),].1 1 f(_(__'__/,l.r,,91 f(g,|.‘r,.6) TLR1\N=\/-Zl “H"; ————)2) -(;;1n—ffi_—A—)2} (Uill 9(9le ’1) :1 “Milt/7) where TLR.NN —> 1N70'r'rll.(11(0, 1) under the null hypothesis: f(;I/il1'2:~ 9) H :E 0 h‘[g(yzi|fl‘i~?) (:0 We will reject at significant level 5% the null l'iypothesis of equivalence of the models in favor of F being better than G if TL RN N > 35% (or TL R, N N < —:5% ). The null hypothesis is not rejected if lTL R, N Ni < 22.5% . 6. Estimation Result 6.1 The data The goal is to get consistent. estimates of the parameters 011 observable barriers and calculate bilateral costs of export. Considering the fact that. country-specific variables and barrier variables. such as distance and common language, do not vary much in time dimension. we instead investigate the cross-sectional feature of the model without looking at the panel data. We use year 2000 world trade data, which makes the analysis cover a cross section of 191 countries. Therefore the data consists of 36290 (191*190 country pairs) observations of bilateral trade flow. Table 3 provides the list of country names. Out of this number, 25611 unique combinations of these countries have zero trade. which is around 70%. Information on bilateral trade comes from World trade. data compiled by 19 Feenstra etc. (2005). Countries GDPs are from Penn \Vorld Table 6.2 and com- 1_)le1nented by the World Bank's “forld Development Indicators (2002). Gravity 12and colonial ties13 measures. including dummy variables for contiguity come from various sources: C EPII, CIA’S \Vorld Factbook and Jon Haveman’s website. The bilateral distance is calculated following the great circle formula. which uses lati- tudes and longitudes of the most important city (in terms of population) or of its official capital.14The number of major cities for both exporters and importers are from Hendersons \Vorld City Data. Table 4 1.)rovides the summary statistics of the variables. The data on regional trade agreement (RTA) is constructed from World Trade Organization documents on RTA dated on Oct. 11, 2000. Figure 4 shows the level of engagement of individual countries and customs territories in RTAS in the year “2000. The figures indicate the total number of each country’s trade agreements. Such a map allows for a quick comparison of different countries and regions. Some countries are not involved in any RTA, while others are signatories to more than a dozen. We use a simple. dummy variable to represent the RTA relationship between country i and j. so I},- 21 if country i and j are in the same RTA and 0 otherwise. 6.2 The result. The exact specifications of the 2-part model of the gravity equation used are as follows: E(DJ-, = 1) = f[)30+1‘31*ln(I",;)+;32*ln(YJ-)+1'33*ln(dist,j)+54*e.r_la:n(llk+ 135 * I'm -10 mil}; +136 >1: com .10 n +137. * com_bordcr+1’38 * Clone/rial +139 * c.r-citics + 1310 * inLc'itics +1310 * III] In T], = 1’30 +131 >1: ln(Y,) + [32 * ln(Yj) +133 * ln(dist,j) +134 * (11:10thde +135 * iIIIJIlIId/k + (36 * comeL + 137 * ("(IIII._b(‘)-I'der + 538 * Clo-name] + 139 * (5’.z'_c'itics + [310 * IIII,_(,“lifI(J'.S' + .1310 * [N + EU where. the subscript. 'i. and j denote the trading partners, exporter for j, im- 20 porter for i: Y1. (I; = 21]) is the GDP: distij is the distance between the trading partners; co-I'IIJII'II‘I'It—‘I‘ is the. dummy variable for common border; Clonom’al is the dummy variable for colonial relationship after 1945; eJ‘Jand/k takes the value of unity if the exporter is landlocked; imJand/k takes the value of unity if the importer is landlocked; e.r_citics is the number of cities in exporter country; -iI‘I2_(‘-Ities is the number of cities in importer country; I fl = 1 if country 2' and j are in the same RTA; E ,j j represents the omitted other factors that influence the bilateral trade; The functional form of f(.) is probit or logit, and error term 5,- j will follow the 1'>reviously specified lognormal or exponential distrilmtions. Table 5 presents the estimation outcomes of various techniques proposed by traditional 111ethods. The first column corresponds to the OLS estimates by using the logarithm forms of exports as dependent variable, and only using the subgroup of country pairs with positive trade value. The second column uses OLS as well but the dependent variable is in the logarithm form of sum of one and trade value, in this way we could also include zero trade observations in the estimation to deal with the problem of no log form for zero. The third and forth columns correspond to Poisson 1)seudo-maximum likelihood estimation proposed by Silva and Tenrcyro for all observations and for positive trade only. In table 6 and 7, we show the results from two part models. Table 6 contains our benchmark estimation. In another word, we treat all the country pairs as equally important without assigning any weight. However, it is not realistic to treat the trading relationships equally for country pairs like US and China and country pairs like Haiti and Uganda, two small developing crmntries. Therefore in 21 table 7, we use two countries’ GDP product. as a weight, so that larger country partners are given bigger weight in the 2PM estimation. The various estimations reveal that the coefficients of log of the GDPs, are consistent with general belief, which is close to one. The coefficients of gravity mea- sures, however. differ from each other in different models. But the general message is that countries further apart trade less, while larger countries trade more. The effects of GDPs and distance measures are large and highly statistically significant, which is in line with the estimates from the literature. Countries belonging to the same regional trade association trade more, as do countries sharing the same lan- guage. the same border, and a shared colonial history. Other gravity effects are quite mixed. The table also clearly shows that the same variables affect both the probability of trade and trade volumes. Comparing the second part of 2PM and OLS for positive trade sub-sample, the following observations are in order. The elasticities of exporter/ importer GDPs, and distance are substantially smaller under 2PM. Common colonial ties have stronger effects under OLS. The negative coefficients on number of major cities in exporters and importers in both models lead to some puzzling results. However. the major interest of this research rests on the marginal effect of the distance and RTA on the level of trade. The results from other models are reported in table 8. And our results from 2PM are reported in Table 9 and 10 separately for estimations without and with sampling weight. Though the marginal effects of distance are quite similar for results of unweighted 2PM and weighted 2PM, the weighted 2PM marginal effect of RTA is relatively smaller than the unweighted result. This could be due to the correlation between existence of RTA for certain country pairs and their trade volume. Therefore, countries that are involved in RTA are also assigned a larger weight. However, this correlation for distance is less apparent. The two model spet‘fifications for 2PM yield larger marginal effect than traditional methods except OLS on positive samples only. The result for the Vuong test is reported in Table 11. The test is applied to probit versus logit and then lognormal versus exponential distributions separately. As shown by LR statistics, there is no significant difference between the methods. The LR, tests suggest that we can not reject one model against the other. As a matter of fact. how to specify the parameterization seems to be rather a less important issue compared with the choice of an appropriate model to deal with the zeros. To summarize, we have been able to find evidence that traditional methods generate biases and are economically incorrect. 7. Conclusion In this paper, we provide a thorough analysis and discussion on the methods applied on zero trades, in light of prevailing knowledge on the theoretical foun- dation of gravity model and the econometric techniques. The general message is that estimates are. biased if zero values are discarded. Additionally, applying two part model to deal with the zero trade problem is more appropriate than the conventional models, such as sample selection. We showed persuasive evidence by ctnnljmrisons between our estimated result and the existing research. The es- timated elasticity of distance 011 trade value and average treatment effect of RTA are significantly different. in two part models from the existing models. To understand the correct marginal effect of trade barriers is essential for our understanding of international trade pattern and policy makings. What policy makers should analyze is the marginal effect of a trade agreement on overall trade level for all possible country pairs, as we showed in the paper. not just for countries that. are involved in bilateral trade. Several caveats are in order. Due to the limitation of data. we can only explore the total trade up to the year 2000. A potential future work is to include more 23 years when data becomes available and look at the time series. Another problem caused by the unavailability of trade data is the precision of the RTA effect. As Baier and Bergstrand (2006) showed, a foreign trade agreement approximately doubles two members" bilateral trade after 10 years. which could not be addressed in our cross sectional data. However, the essential problem we want to address in this paper is the appropriateness of different models for application of zero trade volume and we want to provide the policy makers with more alternatives on an unbiased estimates of the marginal effects of distance and average treatment effect of RT A. The supportive evidence for 2PM against other methods we presented may seem surprising in light. of the prolifr—u‘ation of the traditional ways to deal with zeros in international trade. We hope the further research could acknowledge the importance of zero trades and come to appreciate the need to adjust by using appropriate econometric techniques. 24 Chapter 2: Explaining Export Varieties: the Unexplored Role of Comparative Advantage 1. Introduction The recent trade literature on export / import variety has grown rapidly. The seminal work by Krugman (1979) first brought product variety into focus through a. monopolistic competition model of international trade. Although the i1‘1creases in product varieties have long been known as important source of gains from trade. empirical studies on the significance of the growth of the product va- rieties, or “extensive margin” of trade, in international trade are relatively new. For example, Kehoe and Ruhl (2003) show that. the trade of new goods (exten- sive margin) explains a larger proportion of the growth of trade following trade liberalization than the increase in the volume of previously-traded goods (inten- sive margin) does. A series of empirical studies by Funke and Ruhwedel (2001a, 2001b, 2005) indicates that the growth of product. variety in exports has a signifi- cant effect. on the economic growth in various countries and regions. Feenstra and Kee (2004) also provide evidence supporting the positive impact of export variety on productivity growth for a large sample of developed and developing countries. Broda and VVeinstein (2004) empirically show how much the increase in imported variety mattered for the welfare of United States. Their results suggest that the US. welfare has increased by 3% due to the increase in the extensive margin of trade. Although these previous studies have examined the cross-country pat— terns of product varieties in international trade, few explored the trade patterns of product varieties across countries. In this paper we examine whether the tra- ditional theory of comparative advantage explains the cross-industry patterns of product varieties in the exports of countries. Our approach also considers the mod- ern framework of firm-level heterogeneity. We first construct. a theoretical model in which countries vary in factor emlowment, industries differ in factor intensity, and firms belonging to the same industry are heterogeneous in productivity. This model is used to derive a prediction that. relates product varieties in a country’s exports to the degree of relative factor intensity of industries. To empirically test the prediction we en‘lploy the data 011 US. imports in 1990 from Feenstra, Romalis, and Schott (2002), which finely classifies imported commodities according to the 10-digit Harmonization System (HS). we also use the data on input factor use in various industries from 1992 US. Census of l\*Ianufactures, as well as the data from Hall and Jones (1999) for factor abundance of countries. The empirical tests support our semi-Heckscher—Ohlin prediction for product varieties in trade; that is, countries export more varieties in the indutries that more intensively use their abundant resources as input factors. This paper contributes to the literature by extending the theoretical model of Bernard, Bedding and Schott (2006), which integrates a heterogeneous firm model by l\-'Ielitz (2003) into the 2-country, 2—factor and 2-sector framework, to a multi—industry setting as Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson (1980) and Romalis (2004). The paper also goes empirically further than others by explicitly linking the factor endowment and industry-wise factor use to the number of varieties in their exports. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 develops the theoretic model in order to provide an implication for the relationship between factor proportions and export variety. Section 3 proposes an empirical approach to test the theoretical prediction, and Section 4 describes the data. The results of the empirical tests are also presented in Section 4. Section 5 concludes. 2. The Model This paper adopts the monopolistic competition model with CBS function and a. fixed cost of exporting to account for market entry. The model features a 26 framework where countries differ in endowment and increase in the exposure to trade leads to inter-firm and inter-industry reallocation toward more productive firms and industries with more comparative advantage. We consider a world of two countries, two factors, multiple industries and a continuum of heterogeneous firms. Countries share the same technologies but differ in terms of factor endowments. \Ve use H for home country that is skill-abundant and F for foreign country that. is skill-scarce. so that I— > IT” where S stands - . , H for skilled-labor and U for unskilled-labor. 2.1 Consumption The representative consumer derives his utility from consumption over the output. from all M industries. And each industry consists of a large number of differentiated varieties with each variety indexed by one firm. In what follows, we use 7? to index firms. and m for industries. The utility function takes the following form: N 0: (JV (1' U = (71102 2....Cfi” 2 am 2 1 (2.1) m=1 C m represents the consumption index over industry m, which produces a set of 9m individual varieties, with quantity of each variety as (1(1) 1 em, =[ / qmpdw (2.2) i697” Accordingly, the price index Pm over individual varieties is defined as 1—0 T—l - Pm = [ / 1),”(1) dz] ‘0 (2.3) ’16 Qm 27 where 0 : l-1——p is the constant elasticity of substitution across varieties. 2.2 Production As l\-Ielitz(2003)‘s model, we model the production cost as a combination of two parts, fixed cost and variable cost. The fixed costs are the same for all firms in the same industry within a country. however. the. variable. costs vary across firms with their productivities ,9 E (0. 3c). Therefore. we assume the cost function for firm i of industry In is: (I 9")(m, i) 3712,11,:‘(31713 1 > ,3,” > fill—1“" > 0 (2.4) Total cosf(m. i) = f + si where s is the wage for skilled labor, w is the wage for unskilled labor, A = H , F is the country index. By ranking the skill intensity of industries(,x3,,,), we assume the industries are more skilled-labor intensive as 77). gets larger. The fixed cost and variable cost of each firm features the same factor intensity. There is no difference in factor proportion use within the same industry across countries. For domestic production, the profit maximization rule implies that equilibrium price for domestic sale will equal to a constant mark-up over marginal cost: I" _ " git-3m, 1 (3m . ‘/\ w :- 1’m.i(‘f9) : [)(b (2.0) With the pricing rule. the firms“ equilibrium domestic revenue is in the fol- lowing form: .5377) . 1713171. .‘a ll,} 7‘/\'II),,17(""") Z ("-iyAf i 1-0‘ , ) (2-6) p‘i’PA'I'n YA is the total income of country A. Each firms revenue is ii'icreasing pro- portionately with its idiosyncratic productivity of). the domestic aggregate income [\3 30 1, the industrv price index P,” and the inverse measure of mark-up The profit of each firm would equal the revenue minus fixed cost of production and variable cost: Tm. 1'__(_C5 ) , 3 —3. "m. 1(9) 2 0 _3f)\1 ml 1 111 There is a sunk entry cost for each firm in order to draw a productivity param- eter from distribution C(91). which is a Pareto distribution with shape parameter k with the support. of [1,511. (1le- The entry cost takes similar form as fixed production cost. which used the same proportion of the two factors: #833111, (,1 13711. (2.8) In sunnnary. there is common factor intensity for fixed, variable and entry cost. In the equilibrium, the firms keep entering until the profit is zero, therefore the benclunark productivity for domestic production is determined by zero-profit productivity cutoff: 1 _ .13771 , 1’3, 7"111 (0:111) : afsAm “iA (2-9) In country A, all the firms with productivity higher than or equal to (1'): will continue producing while firms with (,1) lower than the benchmark productivity will exit. The value of the firm is also determined 011 a discount basis of future profit. flow, with (5 as the probability of death, we have: 29 x . - — Ci) 1),,(0) :max{0,Z(1— o)7r,,,(a)} 2 max{0, 17%)} (2.10) i=0 In the long run equilibrium, the expected value V,” should equal the sunk cost in each industry. The expected future value of entry is the er ante expected probability of successful entry multiplied by expected profit, therefore we get the free—e111‘ry condition: [1 — C(Oimfl—Li—m— : fc.s:\37”‘111/1\_dm (2.11) where f,,,(c')) stands for the average or expected profit. from successful entry for industry 111. By combining the free entry condition and the zero profit condition, we could simply express the function of (5):,” in one equation: f 0C , (f) g [( ("1* ‘ Am , * oAm. )‘7—1 - 1l9(6‘>)de = f(.) (2.12) where 9(0) is the probability density function of Pareto distribution. The left hand side of equation (2.12) monotonically decreases with the increase in the value of o: with the right hand side of equation (2.12) being constant. therefore a "I o v * o ‘ ‘ ‘ umque \alue of 0A,," 1s guaranteed. For export, we assume the export cost. includes both the fixed and variable parts. In order to export a. manufacturing variety to another country, a. fixed export cost must be spent for each firm, and it uses the same factor intensity as production cost. Additionally. the variable trade cost takes the standard iceberg form with parameter 7' > 1. this term is synnnetric across industries and cmmtries. \N’ith the export costs, the equilibrium price is still a constant 111ark—up over 30 the marginal cost, A , A , Tsi'nzui—d'nr ‘ ‘ p111.1.r(o) E Tun-.110) : p65 (2'13) For firms from home. depends 011 their productivity levels, their profits will be domestic profit only or both domestic profit and export. profit: ff}; (0) = 7"{),(c$) for domestic production only = 1%,(96) + -7‘,);,j;,_1(cb) for both domestic production and export To solve the cutoff points of export as well, we need similar equations for zero-profit condition and free entry condition. However, the expected profit now consists of two parts: A 7Tm .1totul (1,1)) = figmm) +1113X1017TA1..11(¢)} (2.14) TI The zero profit condition consists of two equations: Zero-profit domestic production condition, which involves 05:7” ., ,8 1— ’3 1~.,1,,(1:,,,) = 0 101911, ’ "1 (2.15) Zero-profit. export condition, which involves (1‘):an ,1’3711. 1‘ #3111 1111110153,”) = 0.115, 1, (2.16) Equations (2.6), (2.15) and (2.16) jointly determine the relationship between cutoffs (1):," and (937,", which is 1 ——k , —k H . 99*Hm. 2 0:71111' A7" (2'17) 31 —A _ —k F qF'm QHmr A"? (2'18) where A51, 2 [Tl—073(%%)0];—k1, A7}; = [Tl—072(fi—g)0]m,A/\ = 5:3,” “ifljm Assumption 1: fr > f With this assumption, there is a selection effect into export market, which means only a portion of firm with successful entry could export. Of all the firms from the borne country, a fraction of C(01).) will exit because their revenues could not (mer the fixed production cost, a fraction of C(QAmr) — C(éAm) firms will serve market A only but could not be able to cover the higher export cost. Only the most, productive ones, those who could draw high enough productivity will export. The free entry condition is also modified because now the expected value of entry is the sum of two parts: the ex ante probability of successful entry times expected profit of domestic production and ex ante probability of export times expected profit from the export market. The expected value should be required to equal to the sunk entry cost, which means: _,\( , . , [ . . 71ml .. 71111 riff) 1’35— 1713-111. 1 _ (:193A111)1+11 _ G()An1.r)1—6— = fe'siymu’)‘ (2°19) By using the two zero profit conditions and the specification of Pareto distri- bution condition, we can write free entry condition in the following way: A . f(Ix —1)15L-A.,,,15F1 +f1( 1 ‘1)“1011111 — f16(2.20) 7721' 32 f(A' — 1)15LA,,,15 1+ f,(I \ —1)15’;I1.5F’* — _f,5 (2.21) 771.17 where [1— — k —+—011‘_ .The existence and uniqueness of {éHmr‘ ‘¢F111.r} is de- rived by linking these two equations. In such a model with multiple industries, two factors and heterogeneous firms, opening from autarky state to costly trade would have different i111pacts on asymmetric countries and on different. industries. As a result of asymmetry between two countries" factor intensities, the profits derived from exporting also vary across different industries in different countries. With other things being equal, we could compare the export varieties (number of exporting firms or probability of exporting) between countries and industries. The ratio of countries" export varieties in the same industry m is given by: 5 , .f..55(AF — f1') 1 _ G(¢5*H111.r) Z ( 1:L )A : ( m 7 f2 (2‘22) OW r (1“ 1)(Af11A111Hf— 7E) The te1m 1— G ( on”) not only stands for the share of firms that are involved in exporting activities, but also represents the export variety of country H in industry because each firm accounts for one variety. It kil—U A (T Assumption 2: ’7' ('91:) <7— > (:,IE)(7—I H This requires both variable and fixed trade cost are fairly large. Under autarky, home country‘s relative skill abundance leads to a lower rela- tive price of skilled labor and of the skill—intensive good. Under free trade without trade cost, both goods and factors are mobile. As Samuelson (1949), Dixit and Norman (1980) showed, we allow two countries‘ relative endowments of the two factors lie in l_)etween of the integrated equilibrium factor intensity, thus the equi— librium of free trade is characterized by F PE, which means the equilibrium wage equals the value for the integrated world economy. However, the existence of fixed and variable cost of trade in our model results in an intermediate relative wage. 33 From autarky to opening to trade. it leads to a decrease in the rewards for the abundant factor. thus the unskilled relative wage 111A will fall in skill-abundance country (Home) and the skill relative wage s/\will decrease in skill-scarce country (Foreign). where the superscripts A. CT. FT indicate autarky. costly trade and free trade. Proposition 1: For fixed country pairs, the cross-industry trade has the fol- lowing patterns: (a) the skill-abundant. countries will export more varieties in skilled-labor i11- tensive industries ( bigger 13 ) (b) the skill-scarce countries will export more varieties in 1.111skilled-labor in- tensive industries ( smaller 13 ) Proof: see appendix B 111 appendix B, we show that the absolute term of industry-lwel export variety of home country increases with skill intensity of the industry. The reason why home country could produce and export more varieties in skill intensive industries stems from the fact that home country has more skilled labor. It could either use skilled labor more intensively for each industry or have more skill-intensive varieties. Our model assumes there is no technology difference within industries across countries; therefore. home country capturing a larger share in terms of exported varieties in skill intensive industries seems to be a natural result. The extensive margin of the trade structure is relative factor abundance among countries. Proposition 2: For fixed industries. the cross-country trade has the following patterns. when relative factor price is controlled, the country that has cheaper cost, 34 in absolute terms export more varieties. Proof: See appendix B There is a bigger mass of firms in the skill—intensive industries in the skill- abundant country (home country), and unskilled labor intensive industries in the skill-scarce country (foreign country). The asynnnetry of the proportion of exporting firms across industries stems from the fact that comparative advantage industry features lower relative price. Therefore, a more fierce competition exists in the comparative advantage industry. but less fierce competition in the export market for comparative advantage indus- try. This fact will result. in more firms entering comparative advantage industry, and thus more export varieties in this industry. 3. The Data Our empirical, framework proposed in the previous section requires data for three variables: the number of product varieties in industries in the exports of countries, production factor endowments in those countries, and input factor i11- tensities in the industries. For the product varieties in exports, we use the data on the US. imports in 1990 from Feenstra, Romalis and Schott (2002). The data contain the infor- mation on the US. imports of each commodities classified according to the very disaggregated 10-digit Harmonized System (HS) from each exporting country. The data also indicate product classification code according to the 4-digit U.S. Stan- dard Industrial Classification (SIC, 1987 version) corresponding to each lO-digit HS. This enables us to count the number of product varieties in each industry in the f(_)llowi11g manner. Defining industries following the 4—Cligit SIC and product varieties following the IO-digit HS, we measure the number of varieties in Industry «i exported from Country 6, or 71 in, by the number of 10-digit HS commodities included in the US. imports from Country c in each 4-digit SIC industry. Since some 4-digit industries have more 10-digit varieties than others by nature, we ad- just the number of varieties by the total number of 10-digit varieties that US. imports from the world in each 4-digit industry; i.e., N,- = :"ic- Note that the imports of the same 10—digit commodity from different coufitries are considered as different varieties, as the theoretical model assumes that each firm produces a unique product. Table 12 provides the number of exporters, total number of varieties, and total import value in the US. imports, as well as those in the US. manufacturing imports (imports in the 4—digit SIC 2011 through 3999) in the year of 1990. Due to the availability of industry factor intensity data, we use the data on manufacturing imports, which represent 94% of the total US. imports in 1990 in the number of varieties, and 83% in the value of imports. The data. for factor endowment of countries are from Hall and Jones (1999). Our theoretical model is in a two—factor framework with skilled labor (S) and unskilled labor (U) and we use the data on the ratio of human capital to labor as the measure of the abundance of skilled labor relative to unskilled labor (S / U ) In the source the data on human capital to labor ratio as of 1988 are available for 127 countries. Since we consider the US. imports from other countries, we calculate the exporters’ skilled~to-unskilled labor ratios relative to the ratio of the US. (1' .e., M for each exporter r). (5/ U )US Our theoretical model assumes common production technologies across countries, and we employ the data from the 1992 US. Census of Manufactures, which covers 458 manufacturing industries classified by the 4-digit SIC (1987 ver- sion; the codes 2011 through 3999) as the measure of the world common input factor intensity in each industry. We measure the skilled-labor intensity of each industry by the number of non-production workers as the share in the total number of employees in each 4-digit SIC; and the unskilled-labor intensity by the number of production workers as the share in the total en'iployi'nent. 36 The sample for our einlnrical analysis includes 115 countries, from which the US. imports in any one or more manufacturing industries in 1990; and 394 111anufacturiug industries (4-digit SIC). in which the US. imports from any one or more exporters in 1990. Table 13 lists these 115 countries in the sample; and Table 14 1*)1‘ovides the summary statistics of relative factor endowment (the skilled labor— to-unskilled labor ratio. or S/ U) of the sample countries, as well as the lists of ten most and least skilled labor-abundant countries. Table 15 shows the summary statistics of the intensities of the two factors (S and U) of 3.9—1 sample industries, and also lists ten most, and least. skilled labor-intensive industries. Figure 4 graphs the number of countries from which the US. imports in each 4-digit industry in 1990. 011 which the industries are sorted (from the left to right) in the order of skilled-labor intensity. Figure 5 and 6 plot the number of exporters and the total number of varieties that the US. imports in each industry, respectively. against industry skilled-labor intensity. These figures indicate that the U.S., the world second most skilled-labor abundant. countries, tends to import. from more exporters, and accordingly import. more varieties. in unskilled lalmr—intensive industries than do in skilled-labor intensive industries. 4. Empirical Test The key implication of our economic model presented in the second sec- tion is that, as indicated by Equation (2.22), with the assumption that each firm produces a unique variety of product, a country will export more varieties in indus- tries in which the country has its comparative advantage in the HeekschenOhlin sense than it will in other industries. In this section we empirically test this i111- plication using the data described in the previous section. 4.1 Measuring Exported Varieties Our model is to explain the munher of product varieties that each coun- try exports to a common importer the US. in our empirical analysis—in each 37 industry by two elements: the exporter’s relative resource abundance and the i11- dustry's relative factor use or intensity. As described in the previous section, we define varieties by the Ill-digit HS connncxlities and industries by the 4-digit SIC, and thus measure the number of a country’s exporting varieties in an industry by the number of the 10-digit HS commodities that the country exports to the US. in that 4-digit SIC. as follows: "17c E No. of 10-digit HS commodities in a 4—(ligit SIC 1' exported by country c However. some 4-digit industries may contain by nature more 10-digit varieties in its catalogue than others, and thus the US. may import more 10-digit varieties in. those industries than in other industries. For a proper cross-industry comparison, we use an adjusted measure of the number of varieties. which is constructed as follows”: 72,}. 4' I 71_slz.a'reljc = where N1 is the total number of varieties that US imports from the world in ' . . y .'. f ,7 _ . . industry 2. A, — 2671“. 4.2 Regressions for Aggregate North and South: \Ve first test our two-country. two—factor and nmlti-industry model with the data for cmmtry aggregates. We divide our 115 sample countries into two groups and construct two country aggregates, one of which consists of countries that are relatively more skilled-labor abundant to unskilled (or with relatively high S/U). and the other consists of countries that are relatively more unskilled-labor abundant (or with low S / U). We call the former country group “North” and the latter “South.” For North we select 51 countries with S/ U relative to the US. above its sample mean, and other 64 countries for South“). Table 16 lists the 38 countries constructing the aggregates North and South. Table 17 con‘ipares the within-group averages of relative factor abundance S / U . The following equation is estimated by the OLS regression for North and South”: [Of/(n-9ll-(Il'ei‘A) = a + ,3 * skill, + 5, (2.23) where 71.13/1a'rcljs A = ZeEA 1'1._slmxre,j. A for A =South, North, and skill, =skill intensity of industry 17.18Our model suggests that relatively skilled-labor abun— dant North exports more varieties in skilled-intensive industries than in unskilled- intensive industries. and unskilled—abundant South exports more varieties in unskilled- intensive industries; thus the expected sign of ,3 is positive for North and negative for South. The estimation results are in fact consistent with this prediction, as shown in Table 18. 4.3 Pooled Regression for Dependent Parameter Specification: We. next use the pooled data for all the individual exporters to estimate cross-industry patterns of the varieties in exports. We consider the following re— gression model: Iog(mshareic) = a + AC * skill, + 5-ic (2.24) The slope coefficient for skilled—labor intensity. AC, would differ across exporter countries. The tl'1eory predicts that the value of the slope coefficient is higher for countries with greater relative skilled-labor endowment. and lower for exporters with smaller relative skilled-labor endowment (or greater relative unskilled—labor endowment). To capture this pattern, we impose the following structure on the slope coefficient Ac: 39 [\(f : l/\((S//L’Y)(j) 2,1131 + {32 * (‘S/LY)( (2.25) where (S/U)C is the skilled- to unskilled-labor ratio in exporter c relative to the US. The theoretical prediction is that the sign of 1'31 will be negative (since A, will be negative for countries with low skilled-labor abundance) and ,‘32 will be positive (since AC will increase to be positive for countries with high skilled-labor abundance). By substituting (2.24) into (2.25). we derive a specification for our pooled regression as follows: log(n5._slm.re,-(_.) 2,131 * skill, +132 >1< skilll- * (S/U), + [1,, + Sic (2.26) \Ve include exporter-specific dummies. NC, to capture the effects of all other factors than the relative skilled-unskilled abundance that differ across countries, such as fixed and variable trade costs and the size of the exporterlg. The result of the estimation of Equation (2.26) by the fixed-effect OLS is shown in Table 19. The estimates of all the coefficients show the signs as expected from the theory, and they are. all highly significant. In addition, using these estimates we compute the "threshold" factor abundant (S / U)* that makes the slope coefficient for skilled intensity Ac turn from negative to positive (i.e., A(:((S/U)*) = 0). The value of the “threshold” S / U (relative to the US.) is 0.6620. These results of the empirical tests suggest that the sen1i—Heckscher—Ohlin prediction of our economic model on the exported varieties is supported by the data on the US. imports. 5. Conclusion I11 this paper. we have investigated the relationship between export. variety and the exporter‘s comparative advantage in terms of relative resource abundance. 40 \Ve generalized the model by Bernard, Redding 85. Schott (2006) to the case with continuum industries and derived a prediction that relates a country’s export va- rieties in a certain industry to the industry’s “degree” of relative factor intensity. To test the prediction we have e1111ployed the disaggregated data on the. US. imports. as well as the data. 011 countries’ human capital and labor endowments from Hall 8: Jones and those 011 the industry-wise uses of skilled- and unskilled— labor from the US. Census of l\/Ianufactures. The empirical tests support our semi-Heckscher-Ohlin prediction. which shows that more unskilled-labor abundant exporter tend to export more varieties of products in relatively unskilled labor- intensive industries, and more skilled-abundant. exporters tend to export more varieties in relatively skill-intensive industries. 41 Chapter 3: Globalized but Unhealthy? Feed- back on Population Health from FDI 1. Introduction: There has been numerous theoretical and empirical studies that underscore the positive effects of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) for economic growth. It has been established that the economic benefits of F DI come in several channels. First and foremost. FDI allows the transfer of the technology, which takes the form of new varieties of capital input that cannot be achieved by trade in goods and services (Feldstein 2000). Recipients of FDI also gain job training which helps to develop the human capital in the host countries. Additionally, profits generated by FDI contribute to corporate tax revenues in the target countries. Since there is such widespread belief that FDI is beneficial to the host coun— tries, F DI has become the pre-eminent source of capital flows into the developing countries, and these governments have implemented a handful initiatives to attract the foreign investment, such as tax incentives. As a result, net inflows of FDI in the group of developing countries have increased almost five fold from an average of 0.44% of GNP during the period 1970-1974 to 2.18% of GNP during the period 1993-1997. Besides all the claims that FDI is a good thing. the hypothesis that F DI would also improve the total living standard outside of the scope of economic growth seems more controversial. Some critics demonstrate that F DI might increase wage inequality (Driffield 85 Taylor, 2000), generate environmental degradation, increase target countries’ exposure to international financial crises and deteriorate the prob- lem of education inequality. In this paper, we explore whether (and how) FDI affects the population health. The population health is an important factor in achieving the. long-run economic growth. Even so, the relationship between FDI and population health has received 42 rather scarce attention, both theoretically and empirically. What makes the em- pirical test difficult is that a simple correlation study on FDI and health does not help to reveal the true casual effect of FDI. The endogeneity of FDI usually causes the identification problem that is hard to be addressed. The level of the govern- ment effectiveness. quality of social infrastructure or international aid programs that may attract (or discourage) more inward FDI would also influence the popu— lation health. For example, countries with less stringent policies 011 the epidemical diseases, such as HIV/ AIDS, malaria and tuberculosis would usually bear the con- sequence of lower levels of human capital, labor productivity and likely higher costs of operations to cope with the health-related expenditures, therefore, less inward FDI would be a natural result. So the key question in our study would be how we can control the endogeneity and ideally, 110w we can find the exogenously calculated FDI level, then look at the effect of the variation of F DI 011 population health. Given the backdrop, this paper is the first of its kind to examine the link between FDI and population health in a cross-country framework and untangle the problem of endogeneity. Levine and Rothman (2006) looked at a similar question whether openness of trade affects child health. They found that overall the trade does little harm. Edmonds and Pavcnik (2006) examined the trade effect 011 child labor and found that the openness elasticity of child labor is much smaller (-0.1) and statistically insignificant. Both papers explore the import-export effect on a country development indicator. A more related paper to ours is authored by Alsan, Bloom and Canning (2006). who investigated whether population health affects foreign direct investment inflows while we look at the causality in the reverse direction. Their panel-data analysis on 74 countries during the period of 1980- 2000 showed that health has a positive and significant efiect 011 FDI inflows for low— and middle—incmne countries. Though the finding is consistent with the view 43 that health is an essential component of human capital in developing countries, their empirical testing more or less suffers from the identification problem. Our empirical investigation on the FDI and health data suggests a negative impact of F DI on the health status, however, the association is statistically in- significant. Thus the cross-country data do not substantiate the assertions that F DI per se plays a significant. role in perpetuating the low levels of health sta- tus that pervade in low-income countries. Country-level inward and outward FDI are from published and unpublished data prepared by UNCTAD. The merit of UNCTAD data is that it is not only collected directly from the member countries, but also is complemented by international organizations, such as IMF and world bank. The population health indicators, including the measures of life expectancy, mortality rates are from World Development Indicator Database. And the gravity covariates are compiled from different sources. The endogeneity problem is addressed with a semi—IV approach. We use the framework proposed by Frankel and Romer (1999) and examine the relationship between population health and FDI based on countries’ geographical character- istics21. The identification depends on the assumption that geographical factors do not. affect population health through other channels besides FDI. Then the constructed measure of FDI volume is used to analyze the causality between glob- alization and population health. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a health stock model and further discusses 110w FDI might affect the health outcome in theory. Section 3 presents the econometric models to identify the effect and the data used in the paper. Section 4 contains the result of empirical analysis. Section 5 concludes and provides discussions on further extension. 2. How does FDI affect health: 44 2.1 Theoretical Review: There are several arguments put forth for exploring the link between F DI and health. We seek to provide a comprehensive and systematic review of the evidence concerning FDI and health service. We categorize the mechanisms through which F DI affects the health condition into five groups: (1) the income effect; (2) gov- ernment policy effect; (3) labor market effect; (4) effects through joint products of economic activities and (5) direct result from higher FDI volume in medical sector. Firstly, a higher level of F DI could overall increase the income level and eco- nomic growth, which would improve health (Pritchett & Summers,1996). It may come from several sources: improved nutrition (Fogel, 1994); improved access to health care or higher government investment in public health funded by the tax rev- enue. A larger income would also allow more extensive medical care: a frequency of routine checkups, doctor visits and hospital episodes. However, transitory eco- nomic growth is usually coupled with more intensive input of labor and health. As Gustmann and \Nindmeijer (2004) showed, there is improved health status with long-term higher income level but worse status with temporary wage raise for the Germany case. Better macroeconomic states might be coupled with reductions in the risky behaviors such as smoking (Ruhm, 2003) but in the meanwhile in- creases obesity-inducing behavior and alcohol use (Ruhm, 2000; Freeman, 1999). Therefore the results are rather mixed in this setting. Secondly, a higher F DI may induce the government to provide a better safety net, better regulations, and as a result, the better infrastructure would have a positive impact on the health outcome. The data shows that there is a keen com- petition among developed and developing countries to attract F DI for its many economic benefits. This drive to lure investment makes different potential target. countries to pursue their own strategies and assemble their own baskets of incen- tives to attract a larger inward FDI. Various reforms and strategies have been ili’1plemented. The improved general business environment, more skilled human capital and the infrastructure of the higher quality, which would have been 011 a smaller scale if it were not. for the incentive of attracting more FDI, all link to a better p(‘)pulation health condition. Thirdly, FDI can be linked to health through the labor market dynamics. The link between FDI and labor market outcome (wage inequality and employment, rate) has been previously explored. The motivation of FDI-either as horizontal for 111arket access, or as vertical to exploit the lower input cost in target developing countries would yield different results for labor market. Though it has been shown by various authors that heterogeneity exists across countries and over time for the determinants of FDI. we contend the volatility of the workers’ wage, employment status and the redistribution of wealth all have an impact on the population health. Health is considered as an input of the production of goods and services. The hazardous working conditions, the physical exertion and job-loss stress could all have negative effects, but the condition could also deteriorate when job hunting period is lengthened when market expands (Karasek & Theorell, 1990; Sokejima & Kagamimori, 1998: Liu et al., 2002). Some sectors that boast higher intensity of inward FDI, such as mining and construction also have higher accident rates as the hire of inexperienced workers increases because of the lengthened working hours to boost. the production (Catalano, 1979; Robinson, 1988). In the meanwhile, the change of lifestyle during laid-off period also has impacts on the health status from a (.lifferent channel. Evidence shows that there is reduction in alcohol use linked with economic downturns (O’Neill, 1984; Evans 8; Graham, 1988). Severe obesity, smoking. physical inactivity. consumption of fat decline as well. For a popular and widely used health indicator, mortality, a. number of studies find a one percentage point increase in the unen1pl(‘)yment rate. is typically associated with a 0.3 to 0.5 percent reduction in total mortality (.Iohansson, 2003; Gerdthanm & Ruhm. 2004; 46 Tapia Granados, 2004b). And infant and neonatal mortality in US declines by 0.6 percent when unemployment rises by one point (Ruhm, 2000). The change of non-market "leisure“ time, gives people more or less health—producing activities, such as exercise. To sum up, the evidence linking working hours and health is also mixed (.Iohansson, 2003; Ruhm, 2004a). Fourthly, FDI influences some joint products of economic activities, such as pollution, also these present risks to health condition (Chay «$5 Greenstone, 2003). The unpacts of these may be particularly pronounced for different. strata of the population —workers who are. involved directly in certain sectors, such as mining, or v1.1lnerable segments of the population. such as infants and seniors. The openness in FDI induces a more fierce competition among firms, which may lead to a “race to the bottom” that increases pollution and reduces govermnent expenditure for investment in health. The last momentum is from General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), which aims to liberalize the service sector to a greater extent, and FDI is considered as the most critical area for openness negotiation. GATS specifies “four modes of supply" : cross-border supply. consumption abroad, commercial presence and temporary movement of service providers. Among the four modes of supply, mode 3 (commercial presence) is considered as the most critical as an influence of FDI 011 the health sector, the benefit. being especially big where investment leads to gains in basic, with additional resources and expertise improving the range, quality and efficiency of the service offered (Chanda, 2001; Zhang 85 Felmingham, 2002). For example, FDI could occur in building hospital facilities or be featured by more medical professionals, in such cases the increased FDI would present more opportunities and be linked with better health outcome. 2.2 A Simple Model: To motivate the empirical specificaticm, we use a modified version of the in- 47 vestment model of health with FDI built in it. Health is considered as endogenous and depends on both the time allocated to it and the medical care. And the amount of these inputs is determined by the time and budget constraint. We denote the representative individual (both agent and principle)"s utility by U as a function of conteinporaneous consumption ct and leisure time It at given time period t: Ut = (.11 Iog(ct) + (12 Iog(lf) (3.1) The production of health consists of time allocated to it (ht) and medical care expenditure (771,). The Cobb-Douglas function would thus be: Qt 2 Ct +131 Iog(ht) + ,8210g('mt) (3.2) Ct is considered as exogenous human capital. With a depreciation rate (5, the dynamics of the health stock could be described as: D1 2 Ct +131 log(ltt) + ,1'3210g(mt(ff)) — (SDt (3.3) The total medical care expenditure is funded by both the domestic government and F D1 in medical health sector (the GATS channel) therefore is a function of the current period FDI (ft). The gain from a higher health investment is represented as a longer life duration, so that more future wage and leisure time could be enjoyed. Death takes place when Dt is smaller than Dmin- Thus the duration of life demuds on Dt. W'e normalize the length of each time period to 1, and wage rate is ”ll-‘(ff). a function of FDI, which could either come from the income channel or labor market channel for the reasons we previously argued. The time spent on working is 1 — ht — lt for period t, assuming away the possibility of tax, the total consumption can therefore be expressed as: 48 Ct. ='U’t(ft)(1-ht —lt) -Ptmt(ft) (3-4) which presents a trade—off between time for health and time for work. The dynamics of the model could be described as the current Hamiltonian H: H = 011<>s(U‘t(ft)(1 — ht — It) — Pt'l'l'ldftll + 0'2 10120-1le /\1(Ct +131 logfht) + 5321080711) — 5191.) (3-5) The levels of control variables 11,, It and ft are determined by F DC as follows: ht : Atlflfu’tfftlfl — ht — lt) — Ptmtfftll a"1'U«’t(f1) (3'6) _ a’2f“’t(ftl(1—ht‘ltl—Ptllltfftll It — a"1U-‘t(f1) (3'7) (1'1 I I (111t(ft)(1—ht—lt)—ptmflft»["l'tfu’tfftlfl"h‘t — lt) _ Pt‘771¢(ft)) — ptmt]+ I /\ 3 mt — 0 (3 8) ti 2mt _ ' 12,; 2 Ct +131 log(lzt) + ,13210g(mt(ft)) — 6Dt (3 9) A, = (5 + p)A, (3.10) p is the discount rate, A, is the Lagrange multiplier for the shadow value of 49 / l . . . health. In, and “’t are the first order condltlon of mt and wt w1th respect to ft individually. The system of the equations characterizes the change path of the health stock. By collecting terms, the total health investment can be expressed by: At1'31(u»‘t(ft) - Ptmtfftll + “’t(ft)()‘t‘31 + 0'2 + a1) Investment, 2 Q + 1'31 log( 0200101) — Ptmtfftl) l"t(ft)()‘t1’31 + 0'2 + 0'1) bet(1-210g( (3.11) where the optimal level of ft is determined by equations of (3.6) to (3.8). In order to determine the impact of F DI on health, we need to further look . BInvestment . . . . at the marginal effect 8ft t, and its Sign 18 determmed by the product I I 513 + 0 ,—_],)t..— m w, — 111 m . The sign is undetermined because of the l 1 1 at I’tmt t t t t - uncertainty of the part (771..th — 1121:7711). When FDI allows higher foreign—aided medical care expenditure without crowding out domestic share, 772.; is expected to be positive. The feedback from FDI 011 the labor market is quite mixed as we argued in the previous section. The impact. from joint economic activities, such as pollution, comes into effect through the term At. in that higher At means a faster depreciation of the health investment stock. Therefore the impact of FDI on population health is ultimately an empirical question for us to explore. 3. Data and Specifications: 3.1 Data: For empirical investigation, we focus 011 two basic measures of health: life expectancy and probability to die (mortality), both measured in aggregate and by gender, age range. Life ex1’1ectaney is the average number of years that a person can expect to live if they experience the current mortality rate of the population at each age. Adult mortality risk is defined as the probability of dying between 15 and 59 years old per 1000 population. Under-five mortality rate is defined as the probability of a. child born in a specific year or period dying before reaching the age of five, subject to age—specific mortality rates of that period. FDI is becoming increasingly important in the global economy. According to UN CTAD (2000) statistics, FDI from developed countries to developing countries grew from 36 billion US dollars in 1992 to 155 billion US dollars in 1999, a level more than three times that of the official development aid. Several sources provide data. on net and gross FDI, including IMF22, OECD publications23and UNCTAD FDIStat database. We chose the data that is the closest to the empirical spec- ification. We. consider a F DI infiow (gross FDI) would influence target country population health more directly than net FDI flow. The F DI data24and affiliate enterprises are compiled from the unpublished data prepared by UNCTAD. The data from 2000-2004 are used and a total of eighty countries have positive inward FDI volume for any year during that period. The total FDI is the sum of three components: equity, reinvested earning and other capital (intra-company loans) on a current. US dollar basis. Other gravity measures, including distance, com- mon language, common border, landlocked dummies, sizes are from Rose (2003). The measure of medical expenditure as a share of GDP is from World Health Organization. Real GDP per capita terms are from Penn World Table 6.1. 3.2 Specification: The empirical work is to understand whether and how the inward F D1 in- fluences the population health condition. For the regression, we first explore the cross—sectional data, and the following linear model is used: For each country i, at given time period t, F DI ,- ” +8.,j (3.12) health-.1: 2 ,Bl + (32 * GDP .2 where the 5% is the volume of foreign direct investment in country i weighted by the GDP, which could be considered as a FDI-induced index of open- ness. The reason why we use FDI—GDP ratio instead of FDI volume is the large variations in GDPs across country incomes. A GDP-weighted FDI measure elim- inates the bias induced by heterogeneity in income levels and represents better the country-level globalization degree. The dependent variable is from the series of the health indicators including life expectancy and mortality (both by sex and in total). Thus :32 would have an interpretation of the change of health measure associated with the increase in the ratio of F D1 to total GDP. However this coef— ficient should not be simply treated as the change of health measure induced by the change in the FDI openness index because we have not dealt with endogeneity issue yet. Another factor we need to incorporate is the channel of per capita income level. As we previously discussed in section 2, FDI influences the health condition through the change of income. It is evident that a higher GDP per capita allows people to spend more on medical care or consume hazardous products, such as cigarettes and alcohol. To capture this effect, we also include the GDP per capital term in the estimation of equation (1). We hypothesize that the relationship between the income level and health might exhibit a non-linear property. Similar to the (mvironmental Kuznets curve (Grossman and Krueger, 1993, 1995), higher income level might be bad for population health because it, provides higher incentive for working extra hours and worsens the health status, but later on it would benefit. health, as countries become rich enough to pay more attention to the health quality. Therefore we further estimate the following: . _ FDI- . . health, = {31+62*ln(5—D—Pz—_)+;33*111(GDPPC)+,134*(111(GDPPC))2+€Z- (3.13) 'I, The term GDPPC stands for the GDP per capita. [32 therefore tells us the degree of association between population health and FDI when controlling the income level. FDI enters each target country in different sectors. It is natural to expect that FDI would enter different industries varying in the pollution extent in different countries, therefore the impact of FDI would have different environmental, thus health implications. Though it is impractical to fully capture all these impacts, we would add more terms besides FDI term in the regression, as a practice, we further include medical expenditure share of GDP for each country in the regression. F DI: . heal 1th,,- : ,81 + £32 * ln( G D PI ) + )33 * ln(medical_e.z:pe:ndit'u.7-eshare,-) + Si (3.14) z 3.3 Control the Endogeneity and Include the Zeros: In order to address the endogeneity issue, we construct measure of F DI- induced openness based on geography, which is proposed by the original work of Frankel and Homer (1999). In constructing these measures, we utilize a. pseudo gravity model for FDI with covariates of geographical characteristics. It yields the following regression: 1.,1FDIfl : [31 + {32 >1: lnsizq + {33 * lnsi:e-+ 7 [34 * lll((ii.‘it(tll.(f(?.l‘j) + {35 * co-Imnon[(1712-3- + (36 * contiguity/U + ,‘37 >1: larl‘u'll()ck,-J- + E (3.15) The logarithm of inward FDI from country j to i is regressed on countries’ sizes, the distance between the importer and exporter, whether they share the same language, same border and whether any of them is landlocked. To predict FDI volume in this way has its own right. Ramondo (2006) used simulated and actual data to justify the approach of estimating multinational pro- duction function using geographical measures. The research shows that similar to international trade flows, gravity governs the volume of F DI. Not only country sizes matter, countries that are twice as distant face 56% higher cost than otherwise. To determine the quality of instrument variables, we need to explore: whether they are correlated with the actual FDI, whether they are not affected by popu- lation health; and whether they are correlated with other factors that influence health. As we just argued, FDI can be appropriately constructed by the gravity measures and the empirical analysis also shows a high correlation between con- structed measure and actual measure. On the other hand, it is hardly true that countries’ geographical features could be influenced or influence the population health. Therefore it is justifiable to say that the IVs affect the dependent variable only through its effect on the endogenous variable of interest --—FDI. Different from the conventional gravity model approach, we only use the country area sizes in- stead of population or GDP to capture the size effect. We are concerned if GDP or population is used, one might cast doubt on their suitableness as qualified in— struments. The GDP itself could allow a higher proportion of income as medical expenditure thus FDI is not its only channel to influence health. The population measure is dubious as well, as population density and the initial stages of the spread of disease are highly correlated (Tarwater, 1999). Many countries actually witness a zero inward FDI. The FDI literature sug- gests the underlying reason of the zero volumes is the high sunk cost of initiating such F D1 in the target countries. Therefore we use a two-part model approach to account for the existence of the zeros and thus we could include them into the estimation. The choice of two-part model over sample—selection is justified by the strand of the literature on a high entry barrier for FDI thus making it a corner- solution case rather than potential missing value (l\rlullahy. 1997', VVooldridge, 2003). 4. Empirical Analysis: The first step of the procedure is to estimate the fitted value of FDI based on the geographical variables. First we use the positive FDI volumes only with the specification of equation (3.15) and report the result in table 21. The the total fitted value of FDI is calculated by exponentiating the predicted values for each country pair then adding up for each target country. The correlation between the fitted inward FDI volume and the actual measure for year 2002 is 0.61. In order to account for the zero FDI volume, we invoke a two-part model approach so that we can include all the possible country pairs and the result is reported in table 22. A total of 170 countries are included in the large sample. With the fitted values of F DI from both approaches, we could investigate the causal effect of FDI on population health. The main regression results indicate that after controlling the endogeneity problem, there is a significant and negative correlation between population health and inward F DI. Tables 23 and 24 contain the results of estimating equations 3.12 through 3.14 using the life expectancy as the dependent variable. Table 23 presents the result of the regression of the level variable of life expectancy on FDI measures while table 24 uses the logarithm of life expectancy. Column 2 includes the result of the association between the actual F DI / GDP ratio and health without controlling the endogeneity problem. A higher FDI seems to link to a shorter life expectancy but the coefficient size is rather smaller. Column 3 contains the result where the FDI measure is predicted from gravity covariates. It can be argued that once the endogeneity issue is controlled, the magnitude of the effect is even larger. A 1% increase in F DI/GDP ratio is C}! Cf! associated with a 0.03 percent reduction in life expectancy. An interesting result is that there exists gender difference in the degree of the impact of FDI on the health condition. The general message is that male is more negatively influenced by the globalization. The analysis on mortality rate yields a similar result to life expectancy. The higher FDI ratio induces higher probability to die for both adults and children below five. A coefficient of 2.5 suggests that when FDI/ GDP increases by one . . r 11111110112" . the mortality rate would be increased by 2.5% for male infants dying before five, and 8.5% for dying between 15 to 59 years old. Additionally, we also notice that there is difference between using fitted values from positive FDI volume only (78 country sample) and all country pairs (170 country sample). The negative impact. of FDI is relatively smaller in magnitude when estimating FDI using all countries in the first step. Presumbly this is because countries with actual zero FDI have a better health status than those with positive FDI. But with an IV-aptn‘oach in the first step, there might be a positive estimated FDI for these countries, thus offsetting the negative influence of FDI and making it. smaller. we also include the a log level of the GDP per capita term in the estimation, positing that it might impact health in a non-linear way. Yet. the analysis shows that the income impact on health is only significant and positive in a linear way, and when income is controlled, we find no statistically significant association between FDI and health. The drive behind this negative correlation might be that lower income level countries are attractive targets therefore have higher FDI-indexed openness. Overall, the results from the regressions show a negative feedback from FDI on population health. With the negative coefficients, one could go as far as the implication that a higher FDI-induced globalization has a negative contribution, but the coeflicients are hardly indicative of the importance of each mechanism through which FDI influences health. 5. Conclusion It is a quite a priori case to presume inward F DI benefits target. country in many accounts. Since the later 19908, F DI has become especially welcome across the world. in the developing countries in particular. Besides some other acclaimed economic distortions caused by F DI, in this paper we look at. the linkage between population health and F DI and address the endogeneity problem in a framework proposed by Frankel and Romer (1999). Geographical vectors are used as IVs for inward FDI. The cross-country evidence shows that there is an overall negative association between population health and F DI. A 1% increase in FDI / GDP ratio is associated with a 0.03 percent reduction in life expectancy. Once the income difference is controlled, there is little evidence that FDI has impact on health. The paper gives a systematic review on the mechanisms through which FDI might affect health. And an investment stock of health model is used to motivate the empirical specification. Though the view of positive economic benefit of FDI has been established, the paper looks at the effect of the FDI on target countries from another perspective. The interaction of F DI and health has received considerable attention in the literature, but the empirical evidence on this topic is scarce. The main problem that limits the empirical investigation is the identification problem of FDI: the en- dowment and policies that influence the FDI level also have impact on the health outcome thus are difficult to fully control for in an empirical setting. In the re— sults, although the coefficient on FDI is negative and statistically significant, its confidence interval around zero is small in magnitude. Though the results suggest a negative impact on health from F DI. we need to interpret the results cautiously. The findings suggest that. a higher volume of inward F DI because of countries’ ge- ographic features does harm to population health but its effect is not, substantive when we control the income levels. It is not the foci of this paper to specifically explore through which channel (and by what extent) FDI influences the health condition though. However, it is definitely something worth investigating in the future. Also, our paper does not concern the question whether better or worse health conditions of the target country would lead to higher or lower levels of the F DI. Also the evidence of minimal effect of FDI on health on average does not imply that there are no circumstances that FDI will negatively impact health. Identifying the atypical circumstances seems to be an importance avenue for future research. Footnote 1. Anderson (1979) was among the first to derive it from a theoretical trade InodeL 2. Hummels and Levinsolm (1995) also poses new puzzles beside replicating Helpman(1987)’s work and in the end, they found the empirical evidence less overwhelming. 3. Data source is World Trade Flow documented by Feenstra etc. (2005). 4. Melitz (2003) (,liscussed the model in a general equilibrim‘n and explicitly solved the number of firms endogenously. 5. As shown in Helpman, Melitz and Yeaple (2004), the parameter k represents the dispersion of the productivities. Lower k means higher dispersion of the firms’ 1;)roductivities. 6. See Duan et al. (1983, 1984, 1985) and Manning, Duan and Rogers (1987). So far they have offered the strongest criticisms against sample selection model. They argue the selection models are intrinsically flawed because they have to rely on untestable assumptions and have poor statistical and numerical properties. 7. Hay, Leu, and Rohrer (1987) showed that two part model performs at least as well as the sample selection model in terms of mean prediction bias and mean squared prediction error, and significantly outperforms it in terms of parameter squared error. In a different Monte Carlo investigation, Manning, Duan and Rogers (1987) put tw -part model in a worst-case setting by assuming the true model is sample selection. When there are no exclusion restrictions, they find that the two part model outperforms in terms of mean squared prediction error and mean prediction bias. 8. Sample selection model is also called adjusted Tobit model or Tobit 2 model. 9. Linear specification of the second part would be inamn'opriate because it generates large standard errors due to the non-linear property of the second part. And in order to use linear specification, we need to add unrealistic assumption of fairly limited range of x and constant partial effects. 10. D21 does not. differentiate two way trade and one way trade. However, the export from country j to i is treated differently from the export from country i to country j; which is to say. two way trade between county i and country j will correspond to two positive records. 11. 1. Prol_)it+Lognormal2. Logit+Lognormal3.Probit+Exponential4.Logit+ Exponential 12. The dummy for contiguity takes the value of one if two countries are adjacent. 13. The colonial ties are defined in the following way: two countries have had a. common colonizer after 1945, have ever had a colonial link, have had a colonial relationship after 1945, or are currei'itly in a colonial relationship. 14. The distance formula used is a generalized mean of city-to-city bilateral distances developed by Head and Mayer (2002), which takes the arithmetic mean and the harmonic means as special cases. 15. The variable to be explained in Equation (2.22) is the probability that an entree firm becomes an exporter. This can be interpreted as the adjusted number of exported varieties, in the following case: The relative number of potential entrees, or the relative size of the mass of potential entrees in each industry is the same across exporters, which is also the same as the relative number of total varieties in the US. imports. (For an illustrative example; the size of the potential entree mass in book publishing industry is twice as large as that. in men’s footwear industry in all exporters, and the US. imports twice more varieties in the former industry than does in the latter. 16. we also attempt two other cutoffs of S/ U to divide the sample countries 60 into North and South; above or below the 75 percentile (29 countries for North, 86 for South), and above or below 0.7 of the value of S/ U relative to the US. ('25 for North, 90 for South). These groupings are also indicated in Table 16. The qualitative results of estimation (the sign and significance of the coefficient estimate) are the same as shown in Table 18 regardless of the cutoffs. 17. nshure is skewed in distribution, and so log—scaled in regressions to adjust for heteroskedasticity. 18. As described in Section 3, skill is measured by the share of non-production workers in the total number of employees. Unskilled-labor intensity is defined by the share. of production workers in the total employment. 19. Recall that we develop the theoretical model in the two-country frame- work. The values of 1*)arameters in the model are likely to be different across country pairs. 20. The mean of S/ U, which is used as the cutoff of North-South in the previous subsection, is 0.59, which is a little lower than this value. 21. The same approach has been used by Frankel and Rose (2003) for analysis on the effect of trade on the environment; Edmonds and Pavcnik (2006) for effect of trade on child labor. 22. Publications include International Financial Statistics and Balance of Payment Statistics. 23. Geographical Distribution of Financial Flows to Developing Countries. The data include gross FDI origninated in OECD countries into developing coun- tries. 24. FDI inflows and outflows comprise capital provided (either directly or through other related enterprises) by a foreign direct investor to a FDI enterprise, or capital received by a foreign direct. investor from a FDI enterprise. FDI includes the three following components: equity capital. reinvested earnings and intra- 61 company loans. - Equity capital is the foreign direct. investor’s purchase of shares of an enterprise in a country other than that of its residence. — Reinvested earnings comprise the direct investor’s share (in proportion to direct. equity 1')articipation) of earnings not distributed as dividends by affiliates or earnings not remitted to the direct investor. Such retained profits by affiliates are reinvested. - Infra—company loans or intra—company debt transactions refer to short- or long-term borrowing and lending of funds between direct investors (parent enterprises). 25. The GDP measure from Penn Table is in thousands US current dollars and FDI in million dollars, so each unit of the FDI/GDP is in thousands. APPENDICES 63 Appendix A A.1: Proof of Lemma. 1 Recall that revenue term (.I. , J 1—0 7... : v. \ J J Willi?) ._ 1-0. . ll] — 7' r] 5(6) = 0f * Hoary) Ufj‘i Then TC,‘ y'. ( )1—0’ .,1.* 2 .-* . A ., Dir-1:11) {A = p".1'ji(l)Pl _( 9v? )1—0szTl—a rear) f y 1..., set-- Y- 1 1 J (Pfifillpj) .sz J .. r] (——...—"J——)1—0 * “(TN-.1.) _f1] _ f)¢:rij(l)Pj __ 99]. 1_0Yj 1—0 W‘T“ . g 1_ 4...») W J Y.) 33, ( W45 ,) " *zzr—z-J " Par/Jinpz Thus l"*.. .. /' _ [Lo-1(2)”: = 9 par — f c- Y- 1 J ”J .7 'fi* .- .p *o - Val-J1 : @Tg_1((l)g ] (22 e? f A.2: Exponential Distribution (A.6) The exponential distribution may be. viewed as a continuous etmnterpart of the geometric distribution. The log likelihood function specifications are similar to lognormal distribution. With the first. setting of probit. for hurdle part and expmiential distribution as the level part: P(D,- =1 64 I . ,’ , (A9) I , . E(Tilsz = LX223 = €XP(X2,-f32) (A10) The unconditional expected value is: . r I r, / Esz'leiaXZi) = Ethlei = LX223 P'T'fDi = 1pm) = exp(X2,:x’32)‘P(A1z-fii) (A.11) The log-likelihood functions will change accordingly to I 111(0) : 171(1 — CI)(X1’:,131)) (A12) J .. . ’ ,, Ti (X21432) and marginal effect of distance is: 0E(T2-) BIA. In estimation part. when we use total trade volume for level of Ti and I}; is the log form of distance, the elasticity of distance on trade volume is: I , ’I I 4. , rI = (I)(.X'1?-_,131);32k exp(X2i;32) + 6(X1ii31);31k exp()&2i,{32) (A.14) 6E(ln trade) I _, ,. , ’ , ’ . = (I) X 3 . r X :13 ,3 . X -3 A.1" 0(lndistance) ( W31)“ 2”“ 11,1) 1“ 2” 2) ( ") 0E(lntrade) I I I , I = X :13 (I) X -;3 , _ — X d3 (I) X d3 . _ 0(RTA) e\1)( 2:... 2) ( 1'Is1llRTA—1 ekpt 2,, 2) ( 11,1)lRTa—f6) When part one is logit and second part lognormal, the unconditional expected value would be: E('Ti|X127aX2-zt) = Emmy: = 11X27i) P7'(Di:1lX1i) (A17) The log-likelihood functions will change accordingly to I ex X .213 111(0) =ln(1— p(, 1” 1) (A.18) exp(X1i/31) + 1 (X, '3 ) T eX) .1 I ' - ln(Ti) = ln(l — I I 12" 1 ) + ln(XQi-flg) - -,—"’ (A.19) exp(X1il31) +1 (X21332) and marginal effect of distance is: I ,_ ,I 0E(Ti) exp(X1?-/31) exp(X1i/31) / , ’ . 2 [32k exp( X 2i ,{3 2 ) + [31 k exp ( X21132) ' .. I I 0" k exp(X1i1_l31) + 1 (GXMXUf/gl) 'i’ 1)2 (A20) The elasticity of distance on trade volume is: I , I , 0E(lntrade) __ exprlifll) $3 + exprh-I'31) I ., . . . — . 2A. 1311.:(X 332) (A21) 0(1n dlstance) 9X1)(Xii/31) + 1 (avail-I31) + U2 27 “’hen part one is logit and second part lognormal, the unconditional expected value would be: I p . I , r 2 exp(X1i,{31) E(TilDi = 1.}(22') P'l‘(D.Ij = IIJYU) = CXp(JY2i,I32 + 0.00 ) I exp(X1,i_/)’1)+1 (A22) The log-likelihood functions will change accordingly to I ex ) X J3 111(0) 2 ln(l — M, 1" 1) (A23) exp(X1,l-,’31) + 1 (X' '3 ) 1 T X' 3 ex n ' — ln(Ti) : ln( 1) ', 12 1 )+ 111(6)( 2 2M 2)) — 1n 0T2- (A24) exp(X1i/31) +1 0 and marginal effect of distance is: I I a}: T- exp 30.05 ( or if TL 3. N N < —:0.05 ). The null hypothesis is not rejected if lTLRNNl S «30.025 - The Vuonng test is applied on the full sample for the first part while only sub-sample with positive values for the second part. The test output is shown in Table 11. 67 Appendix B B.1. Derivation of equations (2.17),(2.18): Use equations 2.6. 2.15 and 2.16, we can get H H {H A 1_0 aft-A 2(1)} (———H H) (B.1) 663‘ P,- F . F_ . F A 1—0 asz —a,Y (pc‘fi‘FP-F) (B2) 1. 2 H H F T14 1_0. ‘ 0 -.A 202:)” —— 8.3 .1. . (pet! Pf) ( 1 F F -H TA 1—0 OfiIA :OiY ( , F H) (8'4) p69: P2. and A)‘ = (s’\)282'-(2w)‘)1_1‘3i Divide (B.1) by (BA), and (B2) by (BB), 2H , H (’0' — f A 1_ (4)01:_l_._0.7 0 (3.5) (3),}: fix (AF) IF . F 01'. )0—1 _ _fz_ A 1—0 (— — -(—)U'T (13-6) 9’95 fir AH B2. Derivation of equations (2.20), (2.21) we can write 7 4.1 2 A . . (1”(‘2’94 ) —1 H 1212»: 1:11— 6(22:A)II<—;\—1" — 11 (3..) ‘32: and (3(0)?) is the weighted average productivity which is expressed as: 271w“) = 1 [/00 ¢0_lg((‘9)d]0l1 (B.8) * " 11 — G16?» 22:1 ' In Pareto specification, ~‘ 51A 1 . Q1222“) = [sac/221110;; )10—1—11 = 11—G<22;1*>III«’—1I = (Ix'—1)<%%;1k " z(13.9) 68 Therefore. the free entry conditions under costly trade would become: f,3(1{— 1)€>i..i..(<.°f‘)_"+ f,,.(K — 1)..,1;,,,,(., .H ,H =f,-,,21 (13.10) f,-(I\'—1)o(‘nin(oF) +f,-,.I( 1 —1)2f;,in(2£)’k = f...) (B.11) Combining (B.10). (8.11) with equations (2.17), (2.18), we can derive a system of two equations for two unknowns: (oz-H )‘k and (of)- linear in these two variables. 1“. Both equations are fj(1\‘ _ IO) 111in\1H((-"1Fit—) k + firiK _ 11‘2‘)‘i(C‘)g)—k Z fie‘s (13.12) F A , "f(1"‘—1)©111111Ai ((2’) 1H.1'—) k+fi.r(I\ ‘ 1)"L( 13)-," Zfic‘s (13.1.3) B.3. Proof of proposition 1: fieMAgi ’ I11) 1.022 7.”) = (—;‘.:‘}}‘>’: = f‘ 2 (13-141 "Di”? I —1 AiFAz-H ( \ )( fi- if?) Then f —k —Im 4H l—A'a—cr 0(1— C(cvj‘JHH: fied‘rl" (fi)fl(affok)(fl*) 0—]‘ (Bl ) . 5 , AH f2 d<71T)(I\ —1) [221(91) ‘Tfi— 41.11)] 291— Ga *H By assumption 2 the sign of ‘ A(H*‘L‘ )] =the sign of (3LT)- which is . (9"?) negative. Therefore, a[1—G(ejfif’)l _ 011*G(<°i.“)l < 0 (B 16) ,1_f}i — :11. ‘ 7.1} F :H_ . 11’ “1 [,2 . Tlns means when —fl is fix E111?" then the increase of 13 (more skill intensive industrv) would result in smaller export varieties. \\ hen home eonntrv is more skilled labor intensive than the f01eign S country. 5% < ”5-11 then the increase of 3 (mole skill- intensive industrv) would result in larger expolt varieties. _11_ . . u. . . [3.4. Proof of propostion 2: VV hen we fixed (W— 2 term. the. negative der1va- (35') tive of equation A. 15 would simplv mean highel unskilled-1211101 cost in home coun- try result in s1nalle1 export variety. Figure 1: Cross-Country Distribution of Trade 90%.. HH__~H_H.2._112._ m%—~~e~~~~wee~ar 4m2~~~e~~~~~~~~~~ w%~e~~~~~e~e~~e~ 20%LHH.~_12___M_._HH~~ m%w~aA~~e~e mm2~H 1+ »»~ 70% ’“ ”HH“*~*~~~~~ 60% I] I loll] I '1'" II | 50% ~24 H H .2 2 2+ b 22 2.-.- 2 0W0 1L1 .Jdt [31 no trade C] two-way trade 2 I one-way trade Years 1980-1997 Note: Years are graphed on x-axis from 1980-1997 All possible country pairs are 36290 Data is from World trade flow, by Feenstra ect. (1995) 71 Figure 2: Geographical Distribution of RTA (Both in force or under negotiation) 120 ~ —————---—-— -— El FTAs under negotiation 100 1-- _____-__xm2,- -21x% IFTAs in force ECU in force Number of RTAs (I) O C C - (U (U 8 ’5 23:17: 8 ‘3 c C m '-< c m .9 ‘1’ n. 3— 6m '5 g E m “‘9 '5': a) a: < “’0’ '0 3 3 ‘60 0 m o co 2 - Lu°5 0 Region Source: World Trade Organization 2000 report 72 Figure 3: Geographical Distribution of RTA as of year 2000 no RTAs 1 to 3 RTAs 4 to 7 RTAs 8 to 12 RTAs 12 to 15 RTAs >16 RTAs HDDDDD Source: World Trade Organization year 2000 Report 73 Table 3: List of Countries: Afghanistan Albania Algeria Amer. samoa Angola Anti gua&Barbuda Argentina Armenia Aruba Australia Austria Azerbaijan Bahamas Bahrain Bangladesh Barbados Belarus Belgium Belize Benin Bermuda Bhutan Bolivia Bosnia&Herzego. Botswana Brazil Brunei Darussalam Bulgaria Burkina Faso Burundi Cote d'Ivoire Cambodia Cameroon Canada Cape Verde Central African Chad Chile China Hungary Colombia Iceland Comoros India Congo Indonesia Costa Rica Iran Croatia Iraq Cuba Ireland Cyprus Israel Czech Republic Italy Korea Jamaica Congo Japan Denmark Jordan Djibouti Kazakhstan Dominica Kenya Dominican Rep. Kiribati Ecuador Kuwait Egypt Kyrgyzstan El Salvador Lao Equat.&Guinea Latvia Eritrea Lebanon Estonia Lesotho Ethiopia Liberia Fiji Libyan Arab Finland Lithuania France Luxembourg French Polynesia Macao Gabon Madagascar Gambia Malawi Georgia Malaysia Germany Maldives Ghana Mali Greece Malta Grenada Marshall Is. Guatemala Mauritania Guinea Mauritius Guinea-Bissau Mexico Guyana Micronesia Haiti Mongolia Honduras HongKong 74 Morocco Slovakia Mozambique Slovenia Namibia Solomon Islands Nepal Somalia Netherlands South Africa Net. Antilles Spain New Caledonia Sri Lanka New Zealand Sudan Nicaragua Suriname Niger Swaziland Nigeria Sweden Norway Switzerland Oman Syrian Arab Pakistan Taiwan Palau Tajikistan Panama Thailand Papua N.Guinea Yugoslav Paraguay Togo Peru Tonga Philippines Trinidad Poland Tunisia Portugal Turkey Puerto Rico Turkmenistan Qatar Uganda Korea Ukraine Moldova United Arab Romania UK Russian Fed. Tanzania Rwanda US St. Kitts&Nevis Uruguay Saint Lucia Uzbekistan St Vt.&Grenadines Vanuatu Sao tome&principe Venezuela Saudi Arabia Senegal Seychenes Sierra Leone Singapore Viet Nam Yemen Zambia Zimbabwe Table 4: Summary Statistics Variable Trade Log of trade Log of importer GDP Log of exporter GDP Log of distances Contiguity Common Language Colonial Ties Landlocked Exporter Landlocked Importer Major cities in exporter Major cites in importer RTA Full sample Export>0 Mean 165511 2534012 10.1249 10.1249 8.77504 0.01565 0.16269 0.0108 0.18848 0.18848 21.8684 21.8684 0.0652 2.2714 2.2714 0.77531 0.12413 0.36909 0.10337 0.3911 0.3911 6.34529 6.34529 0.24688 75 Std.Dev. Mean 562450 9.52777 1 1.6104 1 1.7063 8.60933 0.02585 0.1222 0.02837 0.13981 0.1355 23.825 23.825 0.06742 Std . 4647484 2.75813 1 .90957 1.81652 0.83267 0.15868 0.32753 0.16605 0.3468 0.34227 4.3851 4.3851 0.25076 Table 5: Estimation of Gravity Equations by Conventional Methods Estimator OLS OLS PML PML Dependent variable ln(Tij) ln(1+Tij) Tij>0 Tij Log exporter GDP 1001*" 1.030*** .102*** .360*** (0.011) (0.009) (0.001) (0.004) Log importer GDP .910*** .965*** .092*** .334*** (0.010) (0.009) (0.001) (0.004) Log distance -1 019*” -.647*** 2104*" -.262*** (0.022) (0.024) (0.002) (0.008) Contiguity .473*** .343** 001 _.290*** (0.116) (0.151) (0.009) (0.048) Common-language .565*** .196*** .056*** —0.001 (0.054) (0.049) (0.005) (0.024) Colonial-tie 1.141*** 2866*" .099*** .232*** (0.106) (0.173) (0.008) (0.050) Landlocked-exporter -.376*** -.642*** -.038*** -.096*** (0.051) (0.046) (0.005) (0.020) Landlocked-importer -.677*** -.788*** -.072*** -.193*** (0.051) (0.046) (0.005) (0.020) Num. of cities in expor-.052*** -.057*** -.005*** 0.002 (0.004) (0.003) 0.000 (0.002) Num. of cities in impor-.057*** -.052*** -.005*** 0 (0.003) (0.003) 0.000 (0.001) RTA 0.61*** -0.031 0593*" 0.654*** (0.147) (0.081) 0.000 0.000 Observations 10607 36290 10607 36290 Note: ***, **, * each indicates significance at the level of 99%, 95%,90% OLS stands for ordinary least squares estimation PML stands for Poisson Maximum Likelihood estimation 76 Table 6: Estimation Result: Two-Part Model Without Sampling Weight Probit Probit Legit Logit Probit Probit Logit Logit Lnormal Lnormal Lnormal Lnormal Exp. Exp. Exp. Exp. Part 1 Part 2 Part 1 Part 2 Part 1 Part 2 Part 1 Part 2 Log (ex_GDP) .45*** 100*" .82*** 100*” .45*** .74*** .82*** .74*** (0.010 0.010 0.010A 0.000| (0.005A 0.004 0.010 0.004 Log(im_GDP).42*** “91*" .42*** . .73*** (0.010A 0.010 0.010 0.010A 0.005A 0.004 ”704:4!!! (0.010A 0.020A 0.020A 0.020A 0.010 . A . A (0.040 0.070 0.070 0.070 0.040 0.040A 0.070 0.040A Colonial .46*** 1.24*** Tie (0.080A 0.100A 0.150A 0.100A A 0.150A 0.060A ‘Lan ua e (0030 0.050 0.050 0.060A . . A 0.050 0.030 Contiguity -.38*** 039*" -.71*** 0.40*** -.38*** 070*" -.71*** 0.70*** ex orter (0.020A 0.050 0.040 0.050A 0.020 0.020A 0.140A 0.520 Landlocked -.21*** -.65*** -.35*** .65*** -.20*** -.82*** -.35*** -.86*** Exporter -.004** m-.004** -.05*** -.01** 05*** City number (0.001A 0.004A 0.003A 0.010A 0.001(0002A 0.003A 0.002 Importer -.006** -.O6*** -.01*** -.05*** -.006*** -.O8*** -.01*** -.08*** City number (0.002 (0.003 (0.003 (0.003 (0.002 (0.002 (0.003 (0.002) Log Likelihood -l 34563.2 I -l 34519.4 I -I 39782. 14' -l 39738.33 77 Table 7: Estimation Result: 2-palt Model With Sampling Weight Probit Probit Logit Logit Probit Probit Logit Logit Lnormal Lnormal Lnormal Lnormal Exp. Exp. Exp. Exp. P1 P2 P1 P2 P1 P2 P1 P2 Log .10“ 1.13“” .17‘“ 1.13“" .19“ 93*“ .17“ 93*“ (ex cop) (0.040) (0.040) (0.100) (0.010) (0.040) (0.030) (0.090) (0.030) Log .18*** 1.12"" .32'“ 1.12"" .18*** 1.03“" .32*** 1.03“” (im GDP) (0.030) (0.040) (0.010) (0.010) (0.030) (0.040) (0.060) (0.040) Ln(dist.) -0.07 -.81*"’* -.15*** -.81*"’* -0.07 -.65"** -0.15 -.65*** (0.070) (0.060) (0.260) (0.010) (0.070) (0.040) (0.140) (0.040) RTA 1.05““r 1.32““ 196*“ 1.32'“ 1.05“" .87*** 1.96“ .87*** (0.370) (0.270) (0.130) (0.040) (0.370) (0.190) (0.740) (0.890) Colonial 0.64 .43" 1.27m 43*" 0.64 0.17 1.26 0.17' (0.400) (0.180) (0.090) (0.030) (0.400) (0.150) (1.790) (0.150) Common -.85** 0.29 -1.5*** .29*** -.85** 0.23 -1.53** 0.23 (0.360) (0.230) (0.460) (0.020) (0.360) (0.190) (0.640) (0.190) Contiguity -0.56 -0.52 —.99*** -.52W -0.56 0.09 -0.98 0.09 (0.600) (0.480) (0.080) (0.030) (0.600) (0.290) (1.180) (0.290) landlocked -0.11 -0.12 -.23** -.12*"’ -0.11 -.22** -0.23 —.22** (0.120) (0.860) (0.080) (0.040) (0.120) (0.120) (0.230) (0.120) landlocked 0.01 -0.04 0 -0.04 0.01 -0.06 0.001 -0.06 (0.100) (0.130) (0.070) (0.040) (0.100) (0.120) (0.180) (0.120) Exporter -0.01* -.07*** -.03*** -.07*** -02" -.06*** -0.02 -.06*** (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) 0.000 (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) Importer -0.03** -.11*** -.06*** -.11*** -.03*** -.09*** -.06** -.10*** (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) 0.000 (0.010) (0.010) (0.020) (0.010) 78 Table 8: Marginal Effect Derived From Other Methods Estimation Dependant Mar. effect of Mar. effect of Variable ln(dist.) RTA OLS ln(Tij) -1.0l9*** 0.61 *** positive trade only (.022) (0.147) OLS ln(. 1 +Tij) -.647* * * -0.03l all possible (.024) (0.081) country pairs PML Tij>0 -.104*** O.593*** positive trade only (.002) (0.000) PML Tij -.262*** 0654*” all possible (0.008) (0.000) country pairs Note: ***, **, * each indicates significance at the level of 99%, 95%, 90% OLS stands for ordinary least squares estimation PML stands for Poisson Maximum Likelihood estimation 79 Table 9: Marginal Effect of Iog(distance) and RTA on Iog(trade volume)(with the Trading Partner’s Sizes as Weight Factor) Marginal effect of Marginal effect of RTA Log(distance) Pl: Probit -1.05*** 161*“ P2: Lognormal (0.24) (0.04) P1: Logit -0.85*** 1.61*** P2: Lognormal (0.01) (0.32) P1: Probit -0.88*** 121*“ P2: Exponential (0.24) (0.22) Pl: Logit -.69*** 1.16*** P2: Exponential (0.08) (0-25) 80 Table 10: Marginal effect of log(distance) and RTA on log(trade volume)(without any Weight Factor) Marginal effect of Marginal effect of RTA Log(distance) Pl: Probit -1.20*** 026*” P2: Lognormal (0.025) (0.098) P1: Logit -1.34*** 035*” P2: Lognormal (0.089) (0.096) P1: Probit -0.92*** 0.18*** P2: Exponential (0.016) (0.075) P1:Logit -l.07*** 028*“ P2: Exponential (0.022) (0.074) 81 Table 1 1: Vuong (1989)”5 Test for Model Selection LR Test Statistics Result Probit (Model 1) Vs. -4.193e-O7 H0 is not rejected Logit (Model g) Exponential (Model f) Vs. -8.32e-10 H0 is not rejected Lognormal (Model g) 82 Table 12: US. Import and Varieties in 1990 1111111 Import h‘lillltllilcttll'illg Import Number of Exporting 153 153 Countries Number of Varieties 182,230 171,322 Total Import Value 495,260 409,953 ' (in million S) Notes: 1. The data are from Feenstra, Romalis, and Schott (2002). 2. Manufacturing import is the import in the industries classified as the 4-digit U.S. SIC (1987 version) 2011 through 3999. 3. Exporters in this table include overseas territories of countries. 4. The number of varieties is defined as the number of commodities classified by the 10-digit Harmonization System (HS) that the US. imports fiom each exporter. (i.e., the same IO-digit HS commodities imported from different exporters are counted as different varieties.) 5. Import value is the customs value of general imports. General Imports measure the total physical arrivals of merchandise from foreign countries, whether such merchandise enters consumption channels immediately or is entered into bonded warehouses or Foreign Trade Zones under Customs custody. 83 Algeria Angola Argentina Australia Austria Bangladesh Barbados Belgium Benin Bolivia Brazil Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Canada Central African Republic Chad Chile China Colombia Congo Costa Rica Cote d'Ivoire Cyprus Czechoslovakia Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt El Salvador Fiji Finland France Gabon Gambia Germany Ghana Greece Guatemala Guinea Table 13: Country List (as of 1990, 115 countries) Guinea-Bissau Guyana Haiti Honduras Hong Kong Hungary Iceland India Indonesia Iran Ireland Israel Italy Jamaica Japan Jordan Kenya Madagascar Malawi Malaysia Mali Malta Mauritania Mauritius Mexico Morocco Mozambique Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Niger Nigeria Norway Oman Pakistan Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines 84 Poland Portugal Reunion Rwanda Saudi Arabia Senegal SeycheHes Sierra Leone Singapore Somalia South Africa South Korea Spain Sri Lanka Sudan Suriname Sweden Switzerland Syria Taiwan Tanzania Thailand Togo Trinidad and Tobago Tunisia Turkey U.S.S.R. Uganda United Kingdom Uruguay Venezuela Yugoslavia Zaire Zambia Zimbabwe Table 14: Factor Abundance of Countries: Skilled Labor (S) to Unskilled Labor (U) Variables Mean Std. Min. Max. Dev. S/U ratio 1.879 0.553 1.075 3.369 S/U ratio 0.567 0.167 0.325 1.017 relative to US Number of countries: 115 10 most skilled labor-abundant countries: Country S/ U ratio S/ U relative to U.SA New Zealand 3.369 1.017 Hungary 3.086 0.932 Norway 3.010 0.909 Canada 3.008 0.908 Denmark 2.999 0.905 Australia 2.981 0.900 Finland 2.833 0.855 Sweden 2.825 0.853 Israel 2.818 0.851 Belgium 2.768 0.836 10 most unskilled labor-abundant countries: Country Name S/ U ratio S/ U relative to U.S.A Niger 1.075 0.325 Guinea-Bissau 1.078 0.325 Benin 1.098 0.332 Mali 1.116 0.337 Rwanda 1.119 0.338 Gambia 1.119 0.338 Sudan 1.130 0.341 Mozambique 1.156 0.349 Central African Republic 1.184 0.357 Nigeria 1.217 0.367 Note: The relative skilled-labor abundance to unskilled labor (S/ U) is measured by the human capital-to-labor ratio provided by Hall and Jones (1999). 85 Table 15: Input Factor Intensity of Industries: Skilled-labor (S) to Unskilled-labor (U) Variables Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. S -intensity 0.296 0.124 0.078 0.827 U -intensity 0.704 0.124 0.173 0.922 10 Most Skilled-labor intensive industries SIC Industry Description S—intensity U-intensity 2721 Periodicals 0.827 0.173 2731 Book Publishing 0.766 0.234 3571 Electronic Computers 0.718 0.282 3761 Guided Missiles & Space Vehicles 0.685 0.315 271 1 Newspapers 0.676 0.324 2741 Miscellaneous Publishing 0.638 0.362 2835 Diagnostic Substances 0.633 0.367 3572 Computer Storage Devices 0.627 0.373 3826 Analytical Instruments 0.617 0.383 2086 Bottled and Canned Soft Drinks 0.604 0.396 10 Most Unskilled-labor intensive industries SIC Industry Description S-intensity U-intensity 2322 Men's & Boys' underwear & 0.078 0.922 nghtwear 2281 Yarn Spinning Mills 0.089 0.911 2284 Thread Mills 0.097 0.903 2211 Weaving Mills, Cotton 0.102 0.898 2436 Softwood Veneer and Plywood 0.105 0.895 2015 Poultry and Egg Processing 0.108 0.892 3263 Fine Earthenware Food Utensils 0.111 0.889 2325 Men's & Boys' Trousers & Slacks 0.116 0.884 2321 Shirts, Men's and Boys' 0.120 0.880 3144 Women's Footwear, Except Athletic 0.120 0.880 Notes: 1. The source of the data for factor intensity is 1992 US. Census of Manufactures. 2. Industries are classified according to the 4—digit US. Standard Industrial Classification (SIC; 1987 version). 3. Skilled-labor (S) intensity is defined as the share of non-production workers in the total number of employees; and unskilled-worker (U) intensity is defined as the share of production workers. The sum of S-intensity and U-intensity is thus one for each industry. 86 Table 16: List of Countries in Aggregate North and South North (51 countries) South (64 Countries) Argentina Sri Lanka Algeria Oman Australia Sweden Angola Pakistan Papua New Austria Switzerland Bangladesh Guinea Barbados Taiwan Benin Paraguay Belgium Thailan Bolivia Portugal Trinidad and Canada Tobago Brazil Reunion Chile United Kingdom Burkina Faso Rwanda China Uruguay Burundi Saudi Arabia Costa Rica U.S.S.R. Cote d'Ivoire Senegal Cyprus Venezuela Cameroon Seychelles Central African Czechoslovakia Yugoslavia Republic Sierra Leone Denmark Malaysia Chad Singapore Ecuador Malta Colombia Somalia Egypt Morocco Congo Sudan Dominican Fiji Netherlands Republic Suriname Finland New Zealand El Salvador Syria France Norway Gabon Togo Germany Panama Gambia Tunisia Greece Peru Ghana Turkey Guyana Philippines Guatemala Uganda Hong Kong Poland Guinea Tanzania Hungary South Korea Guinea-Bissau Zaire Iceland South Africa Haiti Zambia Ireland Spain Honduras Zimbabwe Israel Japan India Mauritania Italy Indonesia Mauritius Iran Mexico Jamaica Mozambique Jordan Nicaragua Kenya Niger Madagascar Nigeria Malawi Mali Mali 87 Table 17: Skilled-to-Unskilled Labor Ratios (S/ U) of North and South S/ U S/ U relative to US. (group average) (group average) North 2.4 0.72 South 1.47 0.44 Note: The relative factor abundance (S/ U) is measured by the human capital to labor ratio in Hall & Jones (1999). 88 Table 18: Regressions for Aggregate North and South Dependent Variable: Log of aggregate no. of varieties as the share in the total no. of varieties imported by the US. North South skill 0256‘" -1.21'" -0.041 -0.208 constant -0.256m -1.54m -0.014 -0.063 Observations 394 385 R2 0.1 0.12 Notes: 1. Regression equation is (4.1). 2. skill is skilled-labor intensity of each industry. 3. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. 4. *, **, and *** indicate that the coefficient estimate is significant at the 1%-level, 5%-level, and 10%-level, respectively. Table 19: Pooled Regression for Individual Exporters Dependent Variable: Log of no. of exported varieties in each industry as the share in the total no. of varieties imported by the US. skill_i -272” -O.566 skill_i * (S / U )_c 4.14” -0.802 Observations 17,050 it2 0.13 Notes: 1. Regression equation is (4.4). Country-specific dummies are included. 2. skill_i is skilled-labor intensity of each industry; and (S/U)_c is skilled-to-unskilled labor endowment ratio in each exporter, relative to the US. 3. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered by country. 4. *, **, and *** indicate that the coefficient estimate is significant at the 1%-level, 5%-level. and 10%-level, respectively. 89 6 EmEd A” 25869 c». mxvonoa 8 90 cm. 5 one: 55360815 59,654“ 5 Eco 88888388 208% _. 59538 2.0 58m. 5 came ow mE=oa-_mco_. 38.55. .28 a: mm 9o 30% arm—E9553 383?? Ba 30 1%: mm Ea Ema. N. 92:8 H.63— Zsaus. on 562.8: 8 Cm E 53" 3. =5:me Facade” 3333:2233;3m: $23,332,: ram: :38 Q: :5 62—2. 3. wE__oa-_a—.S. Ema—Ea: 5: W Home arm—.oaiiaew ”58533 :59. 58:me mm cannon mm :8 £58 ow =0: Bonanza: €9.52 5 =5 88— 2552 cm oat—8.8m. 90 Figure 5: Scatterplot of Number of Exporters v.s. Industry Skilled-labor Intensity (U.S. Manufacturing Imports in 1990) 8 888858 B 0 0. 1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Plot: Number of Exporters vs Industry Skilled-labor Intensity (Solid Line=trend line) x-axis is the Skilled-labor Intensity; y-axis is the number of Exporters Note: Skilled-labor intensity is defined as the share of non-production workers in the total number of employees in each industry. 91 Figure 6: Scatterplot of Number of Varieties v.5. Industry Skilled-labor Intensity (U.S. Manufacturing Imports in 1990) 10.000 p ... 1 n O 0. 1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0. 5 Plot: Number of US-Importing Varieties v. Manufacturing Imports in 1990) 0.6 (17 0.8 0.2 5. Industry Skilled-labor Intensity (US X-axis is the Skilled-labor Intensity; y-axis is the total number of Varieties. Notes: 1.The number of varieties in each industry is defined as the number of lO-digit HS commodities that the US. imports fiom each exporter in each 4-digit SIC industry (i.e., the same HS commodity imported from different countries are counted as different varieties). The mapping between the lO-digit HTS and the 4-digit SIC is according to F eenstra, Romalis, and Schott (2002). 2. Skilled-labor intensity is defined as the share of non-production workers in the total number of employees in each industry. 92 Figure 7: Individual Exporter Regression: Scatterplot of Slope Coefficient v.s. Skill Abundance of the Country Fltted Line (weighted) ..+‘.___ _._ —?_._ _ Coefficient of Individual Reg O 01 I U" l l l 1 l l 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 SIU relative to LB 93 Figure 8: Exporter’s Relative Factor Abundance, Industry Factor Intensity, and Number of Varieties in US. Manufacturing Imports in 1990 (1): Selected Skilled Labor-abundant Countries (relative to unskilled: S/ U) O rank14 rank1 5 ii N9 ‘_ x ‘c‘: 99 Average variety Average variety Rank in Exporter number share in 20 number share in 20 S/U ratio most skill-intensive most unskill— industries intensive industries 1 New Zealand 0.01 13 0.0084 2 Hungary 0.0065 0.0076 3 Norway 0.0161 0.0046 4 Canada 0.0758 0.0780 5 Denmark 0.0226 0.0099 6 Australia 0.0259 0.0139 7 Finland 0.0160 0.0057 8 Sweden 0.0308 0.0176 9 Israel 0.0273 0.0205 10 Belgium 0.0249 0.0200 94 Figure 9: Exporter’s Relative Factor Abundance, Industry Factor Intensity, and Number of Varieties in US. Manufacturing Imports in 1990 (2): Selected Unskilled Labor-abundant Countries (relative to skilled: U/S) Average variety Average variety Rank in Exporter number share in 20 number share in 20 S/ U ratio most skill-intensive most unskill- industries intensive industries 106 Nigeria 0.0006 0.001 1 105 Haiti 0.0014 0.0042 101 Pakistan 0.0033 0.0090 84 Guatemala 0.0028 0.0101 81 Cote d’Ivoire 0.0010 0.0014 80 India 0.0085 0.0155 79 Kenya 0.0017 0.0015 74 Turkey 0.0035 0.0078 73 Brazil 0.0147 0.0244 72 Honduras 0.0012 0.0057 71 El Salvador 0.0022 0.0051 95 Table 20: Summary Statistics: Variable N Mean Standard Min. Max. Deviation Life expectancy 170 65.11 11.96 34 81.9 Male life expectancy 170 62.75 1 1.41 32.4 78.4 Female life expectancy 170 67.54 12.62 35.7 85.3 Prob. of dying (per 170 67.25 70.99 4 332 1000) Under five, male Prob. of dying (per 170 61.13 66.54 3 303 1000) Under five, female Prob. of dying (per 170 288.67 172.52 81 902 1000) 15-59, male Prob. of dying (per 170 208.54 166.95 46 789 1000) 15-59, female General medical 170 1.73 0.39 .40 2.68 expenditure as % of GDP GDP per capita 170 9153.43 9607.07 515.50 49367.77 96 Table 21: Countries List (78 member countries reporting positive inward F DI during 2000-2004, UNCTAD) ARE United Arab Emirates LTU Lithuania ARG Argentina LUX Luxembourg ARM Armenia LVA Latvia AUS Australia MAR Morocco AUT Austria MDG Madagascar AZE Azerbaijan MYS Malaysia BGD Bangladesh NGA Nigeria BGR Bulgaria NLD Netherlands BOL Bolivia NOR Norway BRA Brazil NZL New Zealand BWA Botswana OMN Oman CAN Canada PAK Pakistan CHE Switzerland PER Peru CHL Chile PHL Philippines CHN China PNG Papua New Guinea COL Colombia POL Poland CPV Cape Verde PRT Portugal CYP Cyprus PRY Paraguay CZE Czech Republic QAT Qatar DNK Denmark RUS Russian Federation EST Estonia SAU Saudi Arabia ETH Ethiopia SGP Singapore FIN Finland SLV El Salvador FRA France SVK Slovakia GBR United Kingdom SVN Slovenia GEO Georgia SWE Sweden HRV Croatia SWZ Swaziland HUN Hungary SYR Syrian Arab Republic IDN Indonesia THA Thailand IND India TUN Tunisia IRL Ireland TUR Turkey IRN Iran, Islamic Republic of TZA United Republic of Tanzania ISL Iceland UGA Uganda ITA Italy USA United States JPN Japan VEN Venezuela KAZ Kazakhstan VNM Viet Nam KHM Cambodia YEM Yemen KOR Republic of Korea ZAF South Africa LBN Lebanon ZMB Zambia 97 Table 22: Predicting F DI: Positive Volume Only Dependent Variable: inward FDI ln(distance) -.46*** (0.06) ln(target country size) 0.02 (0.02) In( investing country size) 0.04* (0.02) Landlocked, target country -0.25* (0.15) Landlocked, investing country -0.27* (0.16) Common language 082*” (0.16) Common Border 0.17 (0.26) Colonial-tie 0.99*** (0.26) Observations 3 1 89 R-squared 0.04 98 Table 23: Predicting FDI: Using Two-part Model Approach to Account for the Zeros Dependent Variable: inward F DI ln(distance) _3.95*** (0.21) ln(target country size) 1.06*** (0.07) ln(investing country size) 1.06*** (0.07) Landlocked, target country -0994” (0.39) Landlocked, investing country -3. 351:” (0.45) Common language -.53 (0.42) Common Border __15 (0.82) Colonial-tie 8.85M... (0.88) Observations 3 5 532 99 Table 24: Life Expectancy (level) and FDI Ratio (log), Year 2002 Dependent lexp lexp lexpm lexpf lexp lexp lexp Variable ln(ActuaIFDI/GDP) -0.33" (0.14 ln(fittedFDI/GDP) -1.90m -1.98m -1.85m -0.32 -0.36 -1.66m (0.63 (0.59)] (0.67)] (0.47)| (0.48) (0.62) ln(GDPPC) 6.85m)| 14.7)I (0.76 (10.37 [1n(GDPPC)]_sq 045' (0.59 In(med_exp_ratio) 6.84” (2.81)] Expenditure no no no no no no yes indicator Income indicators no no no no no es es Constructed FDI no es es es yes m es Observations 7. 78 78 78 7 78 78| R-squared 0.06 0.1] 0.12] 0.09] 0.56] 0.56I 0.17| Robust standard errors in brackets. GDPPC is log PPP GDP per capita. The instruments for constructed FDI measure are the geographical variables. Lexp: life expectancy at birth Lexpm: life expectancy at birth for male Lexpf: life expectancy at birth for female 100 Table 25: Life Expectancy (log) and FDI Ratio (log), Year 2002 Dependent Variable lexp lexp Iexpm lexpf lexp lexp lexp ln(ActuaIFDI/GDP) -0.005" (0.00 ln(fittedFDI/GDP) -0_03... -0.03m -0.02m -0.00 -0.007 -0.03u (0.01)l (0.01)I (0.01)I (0.01 (0.01)] (0.01)I ln(GDPPC) 0.11m -0.3Zt (0.01 (0.18) [ln(GDPPC)]_sq 001' (0.01 ln(med_exp_ratio) 0.09" (0.04)] Expenditure indicator no no no no no no yes Income indicators no no no no no yes yes Constructed FDI no yes Observations 78 z i 78 7 :1 7: 78| R-squared 0.05] 0.1] 0.1] 0.09L 0.49] 0.5 0.14] Robust standard errors in brackets. GDPPC is log PPP GDP per capita. The instruments for constructed FDI measure are the geographical variables. Lexp: life expectancy at birth Lexpm: life expectancy at birth for male Lexpf: life expectancy at birth for female 101 Table26: Mortality (level) and F DI ratio (log), Year 2002 Variable Mortality Mortality Mortality Mortality Mortality Mortality_ Mortality_ Mortality _young _adult adult young ln(ActuaIFDl/GDP) 1.49" 0.72 ln( fittedFDl/GDP) 7.90" 646*" 2966*" 22.01 *** 0. 0.3 3. I 3 2. 9.70 9.44 0.44 0.3 GDPPC) -37.46*** -218.72*“ 3.08 38. I 3 GDPPC_sq) 10431:" 2.1 med_exp_ratio) -28.37** 14.5 xpenditure no Income indicators no FDI no lations Robust standard errors in brackets. GDPPC is log PPP GDP per capita. The instruments for constructed F DI measure are the geographical variables. Mortality _young: the probability of a child born in a specific year or period dying before reaching the age of five. Mortality_adult: the probability of dying between 15 and 59 years. ln(med_exp_ratio): log level of the total expenditure on health as % of gross domestic product. 102 Table 27: Life Expectancy (level) and FDI Ratio (10g), Year 2002, With Two-part Model Including All 170 Countries Dependent Variable lexp Iexpm lexpf lexp lexp lexp ln(ActualFDI/GDP) -058... (0.12) ln(fittedFDl/GDP) -0.53m -0.38m -0.21 -0.11 -0.46" (0.23) (0.22) (0.24)l (0.20) (0.16)] (0.62) ln(GDPPC) 3,41... -6.56m | (0.42) (1 .01)l ln(GDPPC_sq) .34... (0.08)] Robust standard errors in brackets. GDPPC is log PPP GDP per capita. The instruments for constructed FDI measure are the geographical variables. Lexp: life expectancy at birth Lexpm: life expectancy at birth for male Lexpf: life expectancy at birth for female 103 Tab1628: Mortality (level) and FDI Ratio (log), Year 2002, 170 Countries Variable Mortality _y Mortality 1' Mortality _y Mortality_a Mortality_a Mortality _y Mortality _y Mortality _y male male female male female male male oung male ActualFDl/GDP) 3.1 I... 0.76 ln(fittedFDl/GDP) 2.50« 2.24.- 8.05-- 3. 0. 0.41 1.39 1.30 3.36 3.30 1.19 0.96 ln(GDPPC) -2059... 352)... 2.50 6.1 ln(GDPPC_sq) 4.7]... 0.49 ln(med_exp_ratio) Indicator no Income indicators n0 FDI no GDPPC is log PPP GDP per capita. The instruments for constructed FDI measure are the geographical variables. Mortality _young: the probability of a child born in a specific year or period dying before reaching the age of five. Mortality_adult: the probability of dying between 15 and 59 years. ln(med_exp_ratio): log level of the total expenditure on health as % of gross domestic product. 104 BIBLIOGRAPHY 105 BIBLIOGRAPHY Alsan, M., Bloom, D. & Canning, D.: The Effect of Population Health on Foreign Direct Investment", NBER Working Papers 10596 Anderson, J. and Marcouiller, D.: "Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Investigation", Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84, 2002, pp.345-352 Anderson, J. and van Wincoop, E.: "Gravity with Gravitas: A solution to the Border Puzzle", American Economic Review, Vol. 93, 2003, pp.170-192 Anderstan, J. and van Wincoop, E.: "Trade Costs", Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 42, 2004, pp.691-751 Arrellano, M. and Bond, S.: "Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations", Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, 1991, pp.277-297 Arrellano, M. and Rover, 0.: "Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models", Journal of Econometrics, 68, 1995, pp. 29-51 Baier, S. and Bergstrand, J: "Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members' International Trade?", Journal of International Economics, forthcoming Baltgagi, B. 11.: Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, Second Edition, New York, John Wiley Bernard, A.B., Eaton, J., Bradford, Jensen J., and Kortum, S.: "Plants and Productivity in International Trade", American Economic Review, Vol. 93, 2003, pp.1268-1290 Bernard, A.B., Redding, S and Schott, P.: Comparative advantage and heterogeneous firms, NBER working paper 10668 Biddle, Jeff E. and Hamermesh, D.: "Sleep and the Allocation of Time", Journal of political Economy, Vol. 95, 1990, pp.922-943 Blundell, R. and Bond, S.: "Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic panel data models", Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 87, 1998, pp. 115-143 106 Borensztein, E., De Gregorio, J. and Lee, J.: "How does Foreign Direct Investment affect economic growth?", Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 45, 1998, pp. 115-135 Broda, C. and Weinstein, D: “Variety Growth and World Welfare”, American Economic Review, Vol. 94, 2004, pp. 139-144 Chaney, T.: "Distorted Gravity: Heterogeneous Firms, Market Structure and Geography of lntemational Trade", working paper, MIT, 2004 Choi, Y.C., Hummels, D. and Xiang, C: “Explaining import variety and Quality: the Role of the Income Distribution”, working paper, Purdue University, 2006 Davis, DR. and Weinstein, D.E.: An Account of Global Factor Trade, American Economic Review, Vol. 91, 2001, pp. 1423-1453 Davis, DR. and Weinstein, D.E.: "Market Access, Economic Geography and Comparative Advantage: An Empirical Test", Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 59. 2003, pp.1-23 Deardorff, A.: "Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?", in Jeffrey A. Frankel, ed., The Regionalization of the World Economy, University of Chicago Press, 1998 Dehejia, R. and Lleras-Muney, A.: "Booms, Busts, and Babies' Health", Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 119, 2004, pp.1091-1130 Dixit, A. K. and Norman, V.: “Theory of lntemational Trade”, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. Dornbusch, R., Fisher, S. and Samuelson, P.: “Comparative advantage, Trade, and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods”, American Economic Review, Vol. 67, 1997, pp. 823-839 Dow, W. and Norton, E.C.: "Choosing Between and Interpreting the Heckit and Two-Part Models for Comer Solutions", Health Services & Outcomes Research Methodology, Vol. 4, 2003, pp.5-18 Duan, N., Manning, W.G., Morris, C.N. and Newhouse, J.P.: "Choosing Between the Sample-Selection Model and the Multi-Part Model", Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 2, 1984, pp.283-289 Eaton, J. and Kortum, S.: "Technology, Geography and Trade", Econometrica, Vol. 70, 2002, pp. 1 741-1 779 107 Economou, A., Nikolau, A. and Theodossiou, 1.: "Are Recessions Harmful to Health After All? Evidence from the European Union", working paper, University of Macedonia, 2004 Edmonds, E. and Pavcnik, N.: "International Trade and Child Labor: Cross- Country Evidence", Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 68, 2006, pp.115- 140 Edmonds, E. and Pavcnik, N.: "The Effect of Trade Liberalization on Child Labor", Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 65, 2005, pp.401-419 Ettner, S. L.: "Measuring the Human Cost of a Weak Economy: Does Unemployment Lead to Alcohol Abuse?", Social Science and Medicine, Vol. 44, 1997, pp.251-260 Falvey, R. E. and Kierzkowski, H: “Product Quality, Intra-industry Trade and imperfect Competition”, in Kierzkowski, H. (ed.), Protection and Competition in lntemational Trade: Essays in Honor of W. M. Corden, Basil Blackwell, Oxford and London Feenstra, R. and Kee, H.L.: “Export Variety and Country Productivity”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3412, 2004 Feenstra, R., Romalis, J. and Schott, P.K.: “U.S. Imports, Exports, and Tariff Data, 1989-2001”, NBER Working Paper No. 9387, 2002 Feenstra, R., Yang, T. and Hamilton, G.: “Business groups and product variety in trade: evidence from South Korea, Taiwan and Japan”, Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 48, 1999, pp.7l-100 Feenstra, R.: "Advanced lntemational Trade: Theory and Evidence", The MIT Press, 2003 Fobes, J. F. and McGregor, A.: "Unemployment and Mortality in Post-War Scotland", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 3, 1984, pp.239-257 Fogel, R.: "The Relevance of Malthus for the Study of Mortality Today: Long-run Influences on Health, Mortality, Labor Force Participation, and Population Growth. NBER Working Paper 54, 1994 Frankel, J. and Romer, D.: "Does Trade Cause Growth?", American Economic Review, Vol. 89, 1999, pp.279-399 Frankel, J. and Rose, A. : "Is Trade Good or Bad For the Environment? Sorting Out the Causality", the Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 87, 2005, pp. 85- 91 108 Frankel, J. and Romer, D.: "Does Trade Cause Growth?”, American Economic Review, Vol. 89, 1999, pp. 379-399 Funke, M. and Ruwedel, R.: Product Variety and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence for the OECD Countries, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 48, 2001 Gerdtham, U. and Johannesson, M.: "A Note on the Effect of Unemployment on Mortality", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 22, 2003, pp.505-518 Hall, R. and Jones, C.: “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.114, 1999, pp. 83-116 Hallak, J. C.: “Product Quality and the Direction of Trade”, Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 68, 2006, pp. 238-265 Hallak, J. C.: “A Product-Quality View of the Linder Hypothesis”, working paper, 2005 Harrison, A.: "Openness and growth: a time series, cross-country analysis for developing countries", Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 48, 1996, pp. 419-447. Helpman, E. and Krugman, P.: Market Structure and Foreign Trade, MIT Press, Cambridge, 1985 Helpman, E, Melitz, M.J., and Rubinstein, Y.: "Trading Partners and Trading Volumes", working paper, 2006 Helpman, E, Melitz, M.J., and Yeaple, S.R.: "Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous F irms", American Economic Review, Vol. 94, 2004, pp.300-316 Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W. and Rosen, H. S.: "Estimating Vector Autoregressions with Panel Data" Econometrica, Vol. 56, 1986, pp. 1 371-95 Hsiao, C. & Shen, Y.: "Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: The Importance of Institutions and Urbanization", Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 51, 2003, pp.883—896 Hummels, D. and Klenow, P. J.: “The variety and Quality of a Nation's Trade”, American Economics Review Vol. 95, 2005, p. 704-723 Hummels, D. and Levinsohn, J.: "Monopolistic Competition and lntemational Trade: Reconsidering the Evidence", the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, 1995, Pp-799-836 109 Krugman, P. R.: “Increasing Returns, Monoplistic Competition, and International Trade”, Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 7, 1979, pp. 469-479 Krugman, P: "Scale Economics, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade", American Economic Review, Vol. 70, 1980, pp.950-959 Krugman, P.: "Increasing Returns and Economic Geography," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, 1991, pp.483-99, Learner, E.E.: "The Commodity Composition of lntemational Trade in Manufactures: An Empirical Analysis", Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 26, 1974, pp.350-374 Leung S.F. and Yu S.: "On the Choice between Sample Selection and two-part Model", Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 72, 1996, pp.197-229 Levine, D. and Rothman, D.: "Does Trade Affect Child Health?", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 25, 2006, pp. 538-554. Liu, Z., Dow, W. and Norton, E.: "Effects of Drive-through Delivery Laws on Postpartum Length of Stay and Hospital Charges", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 23, 2004, pp.129-155 Manning, W.G., Duan, N. and Rogers, W.H.: "Monte Carlo Evidence on the Choice between Sample Selection and Two-Part Model", Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 35, 1987, pp.59-82 - Melitz, M.J.: "The impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity", Econometrica, Vol. 71, 2003, pp.1695-2003 Mullahy, J.: "Much ado about two: Reconsidering retransformation and the two- part model in health econometrics", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 17, 1998, pp.247-282 Olsen M.K. and Schafer J.L.: "A Two-Part Random-Effects Model for Semicontinuous Longitudinal Data", Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 96, 2001, pp.730-743 Rauch, J.: "Networks Versus Markets in lntemational Markets", Journal of lntemational Economics, Vol. 48, 1999, pp.7-35 Rose, A.: "Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade?" American Economic Review, , Vol. 94, 2004, pp.98-114 Ramondo, N.: "Size, Geography, and Multinational Production", working paper, University of Texas, 2006 110 Romalis, J.: “Factor Proportions and the Structure of Commodity Trade, American Economic Review, Vol. 94, 2004, pp. 67-97 Rose, A.: "Do We Really Know That the WTO Increases Trade?", American Economic Review, Vol. 94, 2004, pp. 98-1 14 Ruhm, C.: "Economic Conditions and Alcohol Problems", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 14, 1995, pp. 583-603 Ruhm, C.: "Are Recessions Good for Your Health?", Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, 2000, pp. 617-650 Ruhm, C.: "Good Times Make You Sick", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 24, 2003, pp. 637-658 Ruhm, C.: "Healthy Living in Hard Times", Journal of Health Economics, forthcoming Schott, P.K.: “One size fits all? Heckscher-Olin Specialization in Global Production”, American Economic Review, Vol. 93, 2003, pp. 686-708 Schott, P.K.: “Across-Product versus Within-Product Specialization in lntemational Trade”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 119, 2004, pp. 647— 678 Smith, J.P.: "Healthy Bodies and Thick Wallets: the Dual Relationship Between Health and Economic Status", Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, 1999, pp. 145-166 Smith, R. D.: "Foreign direct investment and trade in health services: a review of the literature", Social Science & Medicine, Vol. 59, 2004, pp. 2313-2323 Stewart, J. M.: "The Impact of Health Status on the Duration of Unemployment Spells and the Implications for Studies of the Impact of Unemployment on Health Status", Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 20, 2001, pp. 781-796 Soloaga, Land Winters L. A.: "Regionalism in the nineties. What effect of trade?" The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, Vol. 12, 2001, pp.1-29 Tinbergen, J.: "Shaping the world economy: Suggestions for an international economic policy", The Twentieth Century Fund, 1962 Wooldridge, J.M.: "Econometric Analysis of Cross-Section and Panel Data", MIT press, Cambridge, MA, 2002 111 1liltiljttttttj1111(1))