1'!" . 01”!"ng :53 If. . : z“. s a. rh3.§..%.ufinr Qua ... . Am»: fiam," yawn...» as. 0].. .... "vim? é .. .2; 2.. 5.51:». .s. I 301:; has: iifiufifl ... ? 5‘. nfihx‘ 9. I5 x l I 12.4. ... ...-:73? not... . a. u 3%... | , . ..F .l “Mmbfi% ulfl.l, .. .1. . ..II. a." A {It Era. I! . . . ..9 f..it.>rr::fl . burs. 1: L '3 LUnflrsfi/at; This is to certify that the dissertation entitled ESSAYS ON RETIREMENT AND THE RESIDENTIAL CHOICE OF THE ELDERLY presented by PAULA MEHBOOB KAZI has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the degree In _E—conomics %//@ Mafg’r/firoféssor 5 Signature Date MSU is an afi‘innarive—action, equal-opportunity employer PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date If requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5/08 K:IProj/Acc&Pres/CIRCIDateDue indd ESSAYS ON RETIREMENT AND THE RESIDENTIAL CHOICE OF THE ELDERLY By Paula Mehboob Kazi A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Economics 2008 ABSTRACT ESSAYS ON RETIREMENT AND THE RESIDENTIAL CHOICE OF THE ELDERLY By Paula Mehboob Kazi The dissertation consists of three chapters concerning the well being of the older adult population in the United States. All three essays use data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), a longitudinal survey on health, retirement, and aging. The first chapter studies the relationship between retirement and time transfers within the family. We use cross—sectional variation in the need for caregiving to assess whether caregiving affects the retirement decision. For instance, parents’ inability to take care of certain tasks for themselves, or accumulated and new health problems of spouses could lead to a demand for care from working individuals. We do not find evidence that potential parental care-need accelerates retirement transitions. Also, it does not seem that people retire early to provide care for sick spouses. However, post-retirement health insurance coverage is important in early retirement, in that when people have access to such coverage, they retire sooner if a family member happens to be in ill health. The second chapter assesses the potential usefulness of subjective expectation information in micro data by documenting the relationship between moving expectations and subsequent moving realizations among the United States population ages sixty-five and older. We find that the subjective probabilities of moving are very important in predicting future moving, even once demographic information known to be associated with the propensity to move is added to the analysis. Motivated by the observed relationship between the reported subjective probabilities and actual moving propensities, we hypothesize that when people are asked for a subjective probability they report the true probability conditional on available information, plus some random noise. \We look at the proposed model's implications regarding which population groups are better at predicting future residential moving. However, we fail to substantiate the hypothesis, and therefore, cannot conclusively identify individual characteristics associated with better forecasting. The third chapter examines the long contested issue of whether the elderly draw down their housing wealth during retirement. In examining whether housing wealth declines during retirement, we emphasize exploring heterogeneity across population groups in housing wealth adjustments. Our analysis demonstrates that for non-mover retirees there is no systematic decline in housing equity. But for retiree-movers there is a decline in the median housing equity starting at age 71, and a decline in the mean housing equity from age 76. We find evidence of significant heterogeneity in housing equity adjustments at retirement. Nearly a quarter of the retiree-movers report that they are moving to downsize, and they do. Those with low non-housing wealth and with low income reduce housing equity significantly more than their respective counterparts. Retiree-movers experiencing widowing or divorce reduce housing equity substantially more than those without similar experience. Our findings are, in fact, largely consistent with the existing evidence in the literature regarding downsizing in later life. This study does not disprove or bolster either side of the debate on the role of housing wealth in financing retirement needs. But it highlights that the choice of emphasis regarding which side of the debate holds is often reliant on how one chooses to interpret what is in the data. For/17mm and Bapu iv ACKN OW’LEDGEMENTS I would like to express my deepest gratitude and appreciation for my advisor, Professor Steven J. Haider, for his guidance throughout my doctoral research years. I am immensely grateful to Professors john H. Goddeeris and jeff E. Biddle for their invaluable guidance and advice. I especially thank Professor Goddeeris for the experience of working with him as his research assistant. He has significantly contributed to my learning. Among friends and peers at Michigan State, I particularly want to thank Vandana Yadav, Lebohang Lijane, Linda Bailey, Olena Nizalova, and Lenisa Vangjel for their encouragement, moral support, and many other gestures of kindness. Outside of Economics, I owe a special thanks to Shahriar Hossain; without his help the first few years of my stay in East Lansing would have been much more difficult. I thank with the whole of my being my mother for her unyielding and unconditional love and support in every step of my life. I dedicate this dissertation to her and to the memory of my father — a girl could not have asked for a more loving, nurturing, and supportive father. My brother has been a pillar of strength in my life, and I am always proud of him. The love and kindness of many other family and friends have touched my life. I especially would like to mention my Mejo-Mama and Marni. Finally, I have the most pleasure in thanking my husband, Khan W. Mahmud; his constant love, encouragement, and faith in me gave me the strength to complete this work. TABLE OF CONTENTS LISTOFTABLES ............................ LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................ CHAPTER 1 TIMING OF RETIREMENT AND FAMILY OBLIGATIONS 1. Introduction ........................................................................... 2. The Data ................................................................................ 3. The Descriptive Importance of Family and Caregiving on Retirement Behavior ................................................................................. 4. Empirical Framework for Analyzing the Role of Potential Caregiving on Retirement Tinting ...................................................................... Econometric Specification ................................................... 5. Estimation Results ..................................................................... 5.1 Results for Non-Coupled Individuals ................................... 5.2 Results for Married or Partnered Individuals ........................... 6. Summary and Concluding Remarks .................................................. APPENDIX ..................................................................................... LIST OF REFERENCES ..................................................................... CHAPTER 2 PREDICTABILITY OF RESIDENTIAL MOBILITY: EVIDENCE FROM THE HEALTH AND RETIREMENT STUDY 1. Introduction ............................................................................ 2. The Data ................................................................................ 3. Moving Expectation and Its Correlates .............................................. 4. The Predictive Power of the Subjective Probabilities of Moving .................. 4.1 Relationship between Expectations and Realizations ................. 4.2 Economic Models of Residential Mobility ............................. 4.3 Item Non-responses in the Subjective Moving Probabilities. . . . . 5. The Heterogeneity in the Accuracy of Prediction Across Population Groups... 5.1 What do People Report as Subjective Probabilities of Moving? ....... 6. Summary and Concluding Remarks .................................................. APPENDIX ..................................................................................... LIST OF REFERENCES ..................................................................... CHAPTER 3 DO THE ELDERLY SPEND DOWN THEIR HOUSING \WEALTH? 1. Introduction ............................................................................ 2. The Data ................................................................................ 3. Do the Elderly Reduce their Housing W'ealth as they Age? ................................... vi viii NI—l 13 13 14 16 29 34 36 38 40 42 42 43 45 45 47 55 74 76 79 83 84 3.1 Changes in Housing Wealth through Residential Moving ............ 84 3.2 Changes in Housing Wealth through Equity Extraction .............. 86 4. Why is there Relatively Little Reduction in Housing Wealth? ................................ 87 4.1 Do the Retirees Reduce their Non-Housing Wealth as they Age?... 87 4.2 The Heterogeneity in Housing Equity Reduction ...................... 88 4.2.1 Changes in Housing Equity by Reported Reasons for Moving .............................................................. 88 4.2.2 Do People with Low Wealth Reduce Housing Equity More? ................................................................................................ 89 4.2.3 Adverse Events, Alternative Insurance Availability, and Housing Equity Reduction ....................................... 89 5. Summary and Concluding Remarks .................................................. 92 APPENDIX ..................................................................................... 102 LIST OF REFERENCES ..................................................................... 106 vii Table 1.1: Table 1.2: Table 1.3: Table 1.4: Table 1.5: Table 1.6: Table 1.7: Table A.1.1: Table A12: Table 2.1: Table 2.2: Table 2.3: Table 2.4: Table 2.5: Table 2.6.1: Table 2.6.2: Table 2.7: LIST OF TABLES Reported Reasons for Retirement ................ . .............................. Hours of Care Provided to Parents and Grandchildren ..................... Retirement Hazards With Respect To Living and Care-Needing Parents. Retirement Hazards With Respect To Spousal Health ...................... Effects of Potential Parental Care Needs on Retirement Transitions of Non-Coupled Individuals ...................................................... Effects of Potential Care Needs by Family Members on Retirement Transitions of Coupled Individuals ............................................ Effects of Health Insurance Coverage and Spousal Employment Status in the Context of Potential Care Needs by Family Members on Retirement Transitions of Coupled Individuals ............................... Sample Selection Criteria ....................................................... Summary Statistics of Variables ................................................ Observable Determinants of Moving Expectations and Relationship Between Expectations About Future Moving and Other Events .......... Predictiveness of the Subjective Moving Probabilities ...................... Predictiveness of the Subjective Moving Probabilities By Individual Transition Wave ................................................................. Moving Propensity By Reported Subjective Moving Probability ........... Subjective Moving Probabilities, Moving Propensities, and Mean Squared Forecast Errors Among Different Groups of Population. . . . . Exploring the Mean Squared Forecast Errors in Moving Expectations (For Women) ...................................................................... Exploring the Mean Squared Forecast Errors in Moving Expectations (For M en) ......................................................................... Testing for Equality of Coefficients on Variables Explaining Subjective Probabilities of Moving and Moving Outcome .............................. viii 18 19 20 21 22 24 27 29 31 58 61 63 65 66 68 70 72 Table A.2.1: Table A.2.2: Table 3.1: Table 3.2: Table A.3.1: Table A.3.2: Sample Selection Criteria ....................................................... 74 Summary Statistics of Variables ................................................ 75 Movers’ Reported Reasons for Residential Moving ......................... 94 The Heterogeneity in Housing Equity Extraction ........................... 100 Sample Selection Criteria ....................................................... 102 Housing Wealth, Net Worth, and Demographic Features In 1998 and 2004 .............................................................................. 103 ix Figure 2.1: Figure 2.2: Figure 3.1: Figure 3.2: Figure 3.3: Figure 3.4: Figure 3.5: Figure 3.6: Figure 3.7: Figure A.3.1: Figure A.3.2: Figure A.3.2: LIST OF FIGURES Probability Distribution of Moving Expectations ......................... 57 Moving Expectations and Actual Mobility ................................. 60 Mean and Median Changes in Housing Equity ...................................... 94 Changes in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age ............................ 95 Rate of Home Equity Line of Credit Access by Age ...................... 96 Initial Housing Equity and Change in Housing Equity For Non- Movers by Home Equity Line Of Credit (HELOC) Access .............. 96 Changes in Non-Housing \X’ealth by Age .................................. 97 Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Reported Reason of Moving and By Age .............................................. 98 Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Non-Housing Wealth Quartiles and By Age ................................................ 99 Mean Change in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age 104 Rate of Home-Ownership in 2004 for 1998-HomeownersBy Age 104 Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Total Household Income Quartiles and By Age .................................. 105 Chapter 1 TIMING OF RETIREMENT AND FAMILY OBLIGATIONS 1 Introduction Empirical studies of retirement behavior have generally focused on the influence of financial variables such as pensions, Social Security, employer-provided health insurance, wealth and wages. In a broader framework, however, the decision to retire involves weighing the utility of income against the utility from leisure and other competing time-demands. In an overview of the economic analysis of retirement, Lumsdaine and Mitchell (1999) note that the decision to retire is becoming less a consequence of concerns about one’s own health or need for care and plausibly more related to the provision of care to other family members. The United States General Accounting Office estimates that by 2040 there could be as many as 12 million disabled elderly (Walker, 2002). Based on current trends in care provision, the vast majority of these elderly are likely to receive care through informal networks, typically from a spouse or an adult child (Department of Health and Human Services, 1998). Given the potential importance of informal caregiving, this chapter explores whether there is a direct effect of caregiving on retirement behavior. The relationship between retirement and time transfer within the family has been the focus of a growing body of research in sociology and gerontology. For example, studies suggest that caregiving women are more likely than non-caregiving women to quit employ- ment (Gibeau and Anastas, 1989; Gorey et al., 1992; Ettner, 1995; Pavalko and Artis, 1997; Dentinger and Clarkberg, 2002; Pavalko and Henderson, 2006). There is also evidence that husbands tend to leave the labor force when their wives are ill (Hayward, Friedman, and Chen, 1998; Szinovacz and DeViney, 2000). On the other hand, some studies suggest that married individuals are less likely to stop working if their spouses report work limitations than when spouses are healthy (Pienta, 1997), and that care for parents or ill spouses or other disabled family members does not relate to retirement decisions (Johnson and Favreault, 2001; Szinovacz, DeViney and Davey, 2001; Pienta, 2003).1 In a paper studying the effects of own and spousal health shocks on couples’ labor supply decisions, Coile (2004) looks at the influences of new health events and injuries on people’s retirement decisions and finds no significant relationship between spouses’ recent health shocks and respondents’ labor force exit behavior. In this paper, we use cross-sectional variation in the need for caregiving to assess whether caregiving affects the retirement decision. For instance, parents’ inability to take care of certain tasks for themselves, or accumulated and new health problems of spouses could lead to a demand for care from working individuals.2 To preview the results, we do not find evidence that potential parental care-need accelerates retirement transitions. Also, it does not seem that people retire early to provide care for sick spouses. However, post-retirement health insurance coverage is important in early retirement, in that when people have access to such coverage, they retire sooner if a family member happens to be in ill health. The organization of the chapter is as follows: The next section describes the data used in this study. Section 3 provides descriptive statistics relating retirement and potential family time demand. Section 4 lays out the empirical framework, and Section 5 presents the estimation results. The paper closes with concluding remarks in Section 6. 2 The Data The data for this paper is drawn from The Health and Retirement Study (HRS). The HRS is a longitudinal biennial survey of US. population that had its first wave of interviews in 1Another strand of literature in sociology looks into the relationship between retirement preferences and perceived levels of work-family conflict. See Raymo and Sweeney (2006) for a review of this literature. 2Changes in prices of formal care also can impact the demand for caregiving time, which we do not account for in this study. 1992. The paper exploits seven waves of the HRS from 1992 through 2004. The initial HRS sample consisted of some 7,700 households, in which at least one person was HRS age-eligible in that he or she was born between 1931 and 1941 (ages 51 — 61 in the 1992 wave). The age- eligible individuals and their spouses, irrespective of birth year, were interviewed resulting in approximately 12,500 initial respondents. The HRS collects information on respondents’ demographics, health status, physical limitations, health care use, labor force activity, and expectations about retirement, income, and assets. In addition, it provides detailed data on sharing, or “transfers”, of time and help, money, and dwellings across generations within families. It also includes some basic demographic characteristics of parents and children of the respondents. This study makes use of data on the HRS age-eligible individuals (the HRS-cohort, as identified by the Health and Retirement Study).3 Even though the spouses/partners are interviewed in all coupled households, unless the spouses are themselves HRS age-eligible —— and thus representative of the cohort — they have not been retained for analysis. The Health and Retirement Study over-sampled blacks, Hispanics, and Floridians, and therefore, throughout the analysis of this paper we use respondent-level sampling weights. We define retirement using two separate survey questions: (a) current labor force status, and (b) self-defined retirement status. The current labor force status question asks whether individuals at present are engaged in one of a number of activities, including working, un- employed, retired, disabled, and homemaker. We define retirement as those individuals who report being retired.4 The second question asks individuals to report their current retire- ment status as being fully retired, partly retired, or not retired at all. We retain a slightly smaller sample size when we define retirement using the self-report question. This question is not asked to individuals who report not working for pay currently, including those who are unemployed, or those who are homemakers.5 3The HRS introduced the AHEAD cohort (born between 1890-1923) in 1993 and two other cohorts —— the CODA (born between 1924-1930) and the War Babies (born between 1942-1947) —— in 1998. 4Individuals are allowed multiple responses on the current labor force status question; we do not consider an individual to be retired if the person reports being retired but simulta- neously also reports being either unemployed or working. 5The skip pattern for the self-report question is such that the question is not asked to some individuals. Some of these skip patterns have to do with the interviewer’s perception about the respondent’s employment status, and others include the respondent’s self/ proxy report status, and nursing home stay status. An important aspect of our sample design is that we require individuals to be at risk of retirement at the initial wave. In other words, the respondents had to report working or being unemployed so that they could potentially enter into retirement during the survey period. Thus, in order to contribute an observation to the sample, an individual has to be observed at least in two successive interviews during the seven survey waves. An example of how the sample design works is if a person is working (or, unemployed) in 1992, in 1994, and in 1996, and is reported to be retired in 1998, the person will contribute three observations to the sample. We consider retirement as an absorbing event, i.e., after the first transition into retirement, we ignore all subsequent movements in and out of retirement. In the Appendix Table A.1.1, we discuss the sample selection criteria and the sample sizes for the definition of retirement based on the current labor force status question. We also report the sample sizes for the alternative definition of retirement at the endnotes of Table 1.A.1. We drop all the same-sex couples from the sample. When we define retirement using the current labor force status question, there are certain individuals who conditional on not having retired yet, report being disabled by the next survey wave. We drop these observations when we use this definition of retirement. Before the sample is restricted to non-missing responses on parental and spousal care- need variables, we retain 25020 observations when we define retirement using the labor force status question. The two-year retirement hazard rate for this sample is 20.02%. For men, the hazard rate is 19.13%, and for women the hazard rate is 20.80%. In the sample based on the self-defined retirement status question, the two-year retirement hazard rates are slightly higher —— 20.76% and 23.04% for men and women, respectively. The samples used in the regression analysis are conditional on non-missing information on parental and spousal care- need along with demographic and other characteristics of the respondents. These sample sizes and the two-year retirement hazard rates for coupled and non-coupled men and women are reported in Appendix Table A.1.2 for both definitions of retirement. Table A.1.2 also gives the summary statistics for the other variables that we use in the regression analysis. We describe these variables in detail in Section 4. 3 The Descriptive Importance of Family and Caregiv- ing on Retirement Behavior This section presents some descriptive statistics that capture the potential importance of family in people’s retirement behavior.6 Table 1.1 tabulates the relative importance of reasons that retirees report mattered in their retirement decision. The relevant question in the HRS offers four reasons to choose from: poor health, wanting to do other things, disliking the work, and wanting to spend more time with family. Respondents can pick more than one category as the reason for retirement. Each category is considered as the reason for retirement if the respondent deems it very, moderately, or somewhat important in retirement as opposed to not important at all. An additional category of whether the retirees felt that they were forced into retirement is also reported in Table 1.1.7 We compute the relative importance of different factors in retirement based on the information from 2,418 retiree observations after they make their first transition into retirement during the sample period. Except for the age group of 52—58, family concerns appear to be the predominant factor associated with people’s retirement. For the youngest age group, family is only second in importance to health concerns. Thus, a substantial segment of recent retirees report spending time with family as an important reason for retirement. Table 1.2 shows the amount of caregiving by the recipient and by characteristics of the caregiver.8 Care hours to parents include time spent helping parents (or parents-in-law or 6We display the results based on the definition of retirement that uses the current labor force status question. The main conclusions remain the same if we use the alternative retirement definition. 7It draws on the question that reads: “ Thinking back to the time you (partly/completely) retired, was that something you wanted to do or something you felt you were forced into .9”. 8We use the data on hours of care provision from 1998—2004 HRS surveys. The ear- lier surveys (1992, 1994, and 1996) have a slightly different set of questions on care hours to parents. For consistency, we focus on the last four survey waves in our data. Ptom 1998—2004, of the core sample in the paper, we have a total of 5,544 observations where at least a parent or a parent-in-law is living. 4,711 of these observations are for married or partnered individuals. In 1998 and 2000, questions on care hours to parents are asked only to the family respondent; so for these two survey years we have data on care hours for one respondent per household. In 2002 and 2004 we have responses on care hours to parents from all respondents. In total — of the 5,446 at risk observations — we have non-missing responses on care hours to parents from 3,848 observations. For the 1998 and 2000 surveys, majority of these observations are for women, since women overwhelmingly tend to be the family respondent in the HRS. For care hours to grandchildren we have responses from the family respondent (one response per household). From 1998—2004, with one response per household, we have information on whether the respondent has any grandchildren for 8,215 both for couples) with basic personal activities like dressing, eating, and bathing as well as with other things such as household chores, errands, and transportation. Caregiving hours are reported for a period of approximately two years. The upper panel of Table 1.2 reports the mean care hours for all non-missing responses on care hours (including zero care hours); the lower panel reports the mean hours for those providing positive care hours. Apparently, women spend more care time than men both with parents and grandchildren. With respect to different age groups, there does not appear to be any distinct pattern in the average intensity of caregiving either for men or women. We look into the bivariate relationship between retirement hazards and parental care- need in Table 1.3. We consider parents in need of care when they are reported to be needing assistance with daily activities of bathing, dressing, and eating, or when they cannot be left on their own even for an hour. For married and partnered couples, care-need by both parents and parents-in-law is taken into account.9 We calculate the retirement hazard rates separately for men and women. Column (1) shows the retirement hazards for everyone in the sample with or without a living parent (or a parent-in-law). Columns (2) and (3) Show that conditional on not having retired yet, men and women without any living parent are noticeably more likely to retire by the next period than those with at least one living parent. Part of the difference in the retirement hazards is likely due to the age difference — a difference, on average, of more than two years. Looking into the retirement hazards of people with and without care-needing parents (Columns (4) and (5)), we find that those with healthier parents have a smaller retirement hazard rate than those with care-needing parents. Not surprisingly, the care—needing parents are quite older than the non—care—needing parents of adult children.10 Finally, Table 1.4 presents the retirement hazards with respect to spousal health status. We consider a respondent at risk of providing care to the spouse if the spouse is experiencing any kind of adverse health condition. We take into account several dimensions of spousal observations. Of that we have 6,927 observations with at least one grandchild. Data on care hours to grandchildren is available for all 6,927 observations. 9Table 1.3 retains an observation for couples whenever non-missing care—need information is available either for a parent or a parent-in-law. In Table 1.A.1 (Sample Selection Criteria), this corresponds to the sample sizes in the row “If Parent or Parent-in-Law Care-need Information Non-missing”. 10The parental age for each group reported in the table is the average of the ages of the older (oldest) or the only living parent of the respondents in that group. sickness. The first column in Table 1.4 gives the retirement hazards for the entire samples of married/partnered men and women. Columns (2) and (3) use spouses’ self-reported sub- jective health status; Columns (4) and (5) use the information on doctor-diagnosed severe or chronic health conditions; Columns (6) and (7) use spouses’ recent hospital and nursing home stay; and finally, Columns (8) and (9) draw on the number of limitations in activities of daily living (ADL) that the spouse has. Irrespective of the spousal health variable con- sidered, the retirement hazard rate is larger for those with spouses in relatively worse health than for their counterparts with healthy spouses. Both the respondents and the spouses are older when spouses have any kind of health condition compared to when spouses do not report any health problems. In the multivariate analysis, we control for the respondents’ and the spouses’ ages along with other variables to find out if similar patterns of retirement responses are still observed with respect to spousal health. 4 Empirical Framework for Analyzing the Role of P0- tential Caregiving on Retirement Timing The paper does not delve into developing a formal utility maximization framework, and we cannot a priori predict the direction of causality from family time demand to retirement patterns. Nonetheless, we make a presumption, shaped by the descriptive statistics presented earlier, that labor force participants who assume an informal caregiving role may derive dif- ferent utility from continued work than non-caregivers. Consequently, the former group may retire from the labor force at a higher rate than the latter group. A health shock may alter the value of the time shared between a couple or between a parent and an adult child. This may be so because the affected spouse or parent may need more assistance with activities of daily living, or because the sick family member has a shortened lifespan. At times, however, financial considerations — and thus, the need for continuing employment — can become predominant over the need for caregiving in determining people’s retirement behavior. This may be particularly important in the context of financing out-of—pocket health care costs for family members. Sources of spousal health insurance coverage as well as the potential for accessing care from alternate caregivers may also influence individual retirement decision. All in all, the response of retirement timing to adverse health events or care-need in the family is theoretically ambiguous and may differ across families. Econometric Specification The empirical strategy of this paper is to specify and estimate a reduced form retirement model to examine the potential role of caregiving. We consider a discrete time hazard model, where the binary variable Bit equals 1 if a person not having retired in the previous time period t—l retires by the current time period t. Also, let the binary variable Cit equal 1 if at time t an individual is at risk of caregiving to a parent or the spouse/partner. Consider the probit model, PTlRit=1l= N30 + (31th + 3222',“ + 53021: + 541%) (1) where f is the normal density. X denotes a set of demographic characteristics pertaining to the respondent, and Z represents variables that capture information related to the job held in the previous period. Since the retirees no longer have job attachments at the current period, information like earnings from employment are used from the last period’s jobs“. C captures the potential care-need variables, and F represents additional information about family members and family composition. We estimate the retirement model separately for the non-coupled group and the coupled group. Retirement responses of these two groups have been found to be somewhat different”, and since married or partnered individuals have an additional set of family members who can potentially create time demands, it seems a reasonable approach. When there is only one respondent from a household, and the respondent identifies him/herself as never married, widowed, or separated / divorced, we include that person in the non-coupled sample. Married or partnered respondents contribute to the coupled sample. For the non-coupled individuals (singles), the only source of family obligation we consider is parents; whereas, for the coupled individuals (couples), potential care-need may arise from parents, parents-in-law”, as well 11For individuals who are at risk of retirement but are unemployed, earnings can be zero if no job is held during the survey year. 12For instance, Lumsdaine, Stock, and Wise (1996) find that married men are significantly more likely to retire at age 65 than single men. 13The parents of cohabiting partners are considered as parents-in-law, and their siblings as 8 as the spouse/ partner. We estimate the probit model separately for men and women. Recall that parental care-need is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the respondent reports that at least one parent requires assistance with basic daily activities, such as, dressing, bathing, and eating, or that the parent cannot be left alone even for an hour. If the respon- dent answers either of these two parental care-need related questions in the HRS for at least one parent, we have a non-missing observation for the parental care-need variable. A similar care-need variable for parents-in-law is defined for married and partnered individuals. We consider two different specifications, with the difference stemming solely from the set of parental care-need variables that we use. In one specification, the parental variables included are — (1) all living parents healthy, (2) Mom and Dad married and both of them in need of care, 0R Mom/Dad unmarried and in need of care, (3) Mom and Dad married and one of them in need of care, and (4) Mom/Dad married to stepparent and in need of care —— with no living parent as the omitted category. The category all living parents healthy is equal to 1 if none of the living parents needs care. The rest of the categories account for parental marital status. After all, the spouse of a care-needing parent may be capable of taking care of the ailing parent. Thus, the adult child’s retirement response may be impacted by whether the care-needing parent has a potentially caregiving spouse or not. In the HRS, questions are not asked regarding the health of the stepparent. Therefore, M om/Dad married to stepparent and in need of care is considered as a separate category from the categories reflecting the health status of biological parents. Mom and Dad married and both of them in need of care and Mom/Dad unmarried and in need of care are combined into one variable, as in both cases there is no healthy care-providing partner for the ailing parent. In the other specification, the parental variables included are — (1) Mom or Dad or both living, and (2) Mom or Dad or both in need of care. The second variable does not distinguish potential parental care-need by parental marital status. We have a more parsimonious estimation with this set of parental variables. Since only small fractions of the sample have parents meeting the criteria Mom and Dad married and one of them in need of care and Mom/Dad married to stepparent and in need of care (see Table 1.A.2 for summary statistics of the parental care-need variables), this seems a useful alternative specification. When we siblings-in-law. estimate the retirement model for couples, the two specifications include dummy variables for parents-in-law corresponding to all the variables for parents. We prefer including separate variables for own and spousal parents, as people might respond differently to the health needs of parents and parents-in-law.l4 As proxies for potential care-need arising from ailing spouses, we consider several vari- ables: (1) whether the spouse has ever had any chronic health condition“, (2) whether the spouse has ever had any severe health condition”, (3) whether the spouse has any difl‘icul— ties with activities of daily living (ADL)”, and (4) whether the spouse has developed any new chronic or severe health condition in the past two years.18 The first three variables are expected to capture the overall level of spousal health. The fourth one is included in the specifications to account for any additional effects of new or worsening health events on re- tirement hazards. When a spouse gets sick, the unaffected spouse may not choose to retire in the immediate next period. But it is plausible that when the sick spouse does not recover, his/ her sickness still affects the healthy spouse’s decision to retire in the following periods, although there may have been no further deterioration in the sick spouse’s health condition in the recent past. As such, in addition to recent occurrences of health shocks, we account for the level of spousal health status. Ideally, we would have wanted to include in the specifications one set of dummy vari- ables reflecting simultaneously potential care-need from any and all family members, instead of including separate sets of variables for parents, parents-in-law, and the spouse/partner. However, for certain combinations of health status for different family members we either have no observations, or have too few observations with no variation in the outcome variable of interest. Siblings could represent an alternate source of informal care for parents. With this in mind, the estimations include a variable indicating whether the individual has any siblings. 14We lose some observations when we use the longer list of parental variables, due to some non-responses on parental care-need when both parents are married to each other (see Table 1.A.1 endnotes 6 and 8). 15Chronic health conditions include high blood pressure, diabetes, lung disease, arthritis, and psychological problems. 16Severe health conditions include cancer, heart problem (heart attack or heart surgery), and stroke. 17In addition to the doctor-diagnosed medical conditions, we include the variable for any limitation in ADL, because activity limitations may aggravate the health effects of retirement. 18Summary statistics for these variables are given in Table 1.A.2. 10 We also include an interaction tern between this sibling indicator variable and Mom or Dad or both in need of care. The variable Mom or Dad or both in need of care is captured by four separate variables when we use the longer list of parental variables, but in that specification it is econometrically feasible to use this one variable in the interaction term. The sum of the estimated coefficients on Any sibling and Any sibling*Mom or Dad or both in need of care tells us whether someone with a sibling and a care-needing parent has a different re- tirement response than someone without a sibling but with a parent in need of care. In the estimation of the coupled sample, a similar set of variables — Spouse has any sibling and Spouse has any sibling*Mom-in-law or Dad-in-law or both in need of care — are included to account for the role of siblings-in-law in providing care for parents-in—law. We include another interaction variable representing the importance of siblings-in—law in providing care for the respondents’ spouses — Spouse has any sibling*Sp0use has new chronic or severe health condition. Conditional on overall health status and ADL limitations, spousal new health events may influence retirement response. As such, we use Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition in the interaction variables involving spousal health.19 The estima- tions on couples include two additional interaction terms: Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition*M0m or Dad or both in need of care and Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition*Mom-in-law or Dad-in-law or both in need of care. These interactions, in conjunction with their level variables, capture the retirement responses of individuals with different number and combination of care-needing family members. We include four health variables for the respondents, similar to the ones described for the spouses, in all regressions. In couples’ regressions, we also add an indicator variable for Spouse not working at present. Hurd (1990) and Blau (1998) find that about one-third of couples in which both spouses are in the labor force at age 50 retire within one year of each other. Thus, if a respondent’s spouse is not working and also happens to be in need of care, the individual’s retirement response might be determined by the spousal labor force status and not spousal illness. The interaction variable between Spouse not working at present and Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition along with the spousal sickness variable then tells us whether retirement response differs with respect to potential spousal care-need 19It should be emphasized that the estimations have been rerun with interaction terms using the alternative spousal health variables, and the results do not differ qualitatively. 11 when the spouse is not working. The variable Retiree health insurance, Medicare or other health coverage is a dummy vari- able equal to 1 if the individual is eligible for retiree health insurance20 from the job held last period, or is covered by a long-term care insurance, or is enrolled in any type of federal gov- ernment health insurance program, e.g., Medicare, Medicaid, CHAMPUS/VA/TRICARE, or any other government health insurance.21 We include in the regressions an interaction term between Retiree health insurance, Medicare or other health coverage (RHI-M, for short) and Mom or Dad or both in need of care to capture if access to post-retirement health coverage makes people respond differently to parental care-need. Similarly, we include the interaction term Retiree health insurance, Medicare or other health coverage*Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition in couples’ regressions to account for possible differential retirement responses to spousal care-need with respect to eligibility for RHI-M. Often people have health insurance coverage through the employers of their spouses. When the respondents’ employer-sponsored health insurances cover the spouses, it might slow retirement transition for the individuals. This seems more likely if the spouse’s health condition involves potentially large health care costs. The slowing effect on retirement transi- tion could be offset if the spouse is Medicare eligible, or has retiree health insurance, or some other federal health coverage. Even with spousal access to Medicare or other insurances, it might happen that the respondents’ employer-provided health plans are simply better, and therefore, respondents might still defer retirement. To understand these effects of health insurances, we add in the regressions a dummy variable Spouse has retiree health insurance, Medicare or other health coverage (SRHI-M), and a dummy variable Spouse is covered by respondent’s employer-provided health insurance, as well as an interaction term of these two variables. The other control variables in the specifications are dummy variables for respondent age, dummy variables for education, the total yearly earnings from the job held, the total house- 20Employer-provided retiree health insurance permits individuals to remain in the health insurance plan of their career employer after retirement at a lower cost than they would face purchasing similar coverage in the market. The role of retiree health insurance can be particularly important when retirement occurs before the Medicare eligibility age of 65. 21All the regressions — both for the samples of singles and couples — have also been estimated with an alternate post-retirement health insurance variable that includes, instead of all government health programs, only Medicare. There is no important difference in the results using either of the two variables. 12 hold income, and the total non-housing assets22 (all in year-2000 dollars and re-scaled)”. As crude proxies for pension wealth, we include three indicator variables for defined bene— fit pension, defined contribution pension, and a combination of defined benefit and defined contribution pension (with no pension enrollment as the omitted category). Dummy vari- ables for the HRS survey years are also included. Estimations using the sample of couples include a quadratic in spousal age. In the estimations with the non-coupled sample, since the individuals are never married, widowed, or separated/ divorced, two dummy variables —— widowed and separated/divorced — are included in the regressions. Similarly, two dummy variables — married with spouse absent and partnered — enter the regressions using the couples’ sample. 5 Estimation Results Table 1.5 presents the estimation results for the non-coupled individuals, and Tables 1.6 and 1.7 present the results for the couples. The results in these tables are from the probit estimations using the retirement variable based on the current labor force status question.24 5.1 Results for Non-Coupled Individuals From Table 1.5 there does not appear to be any statistically significant positive association between potential parental care-need and the retirement transition of non-coupled men and women. If anything, we find evidence of statistically significant delaying effect on retirement for certain combinations of parental care-need and marital status (Columns 5 and 7 for men and Columns 6 and 8 for women).25 With respect to the potential role of siblings as alternate 22Non-housing assets defined as the sum of the net value of real estate (not primary resi- dence), the net value of vehicles and businesses, IRA, Keogh accounts, stocks, mutual funds, and investment trusts, the value of checking, savings, or money market accounts, CD, gov- ernment bonds, and T-bills, the net value of bonds and bond funds, and the net value of all other savings, less the value of other debts. The values of primary residence, mortgages, and other home loans are not included. 23Data on earnings, household income, and non-housing assets are taken from the RAND HRS files (See St. Clair et al., 2006). 24We also estimate the retirement model using the alternative retirement variable based on the self-defined retirement status question. The results are basically identical. 25For women, the negative effect of Mom or Dad or both in need of care in Column (4) and that of Mom and Dad married and both of them in need of care, OR Mom/Dad unmarried and in need of care in Column (8) of Table 1.5 are statistically significant when we estimate the model using the self-defined retirement hazard variable. 13 caregivers, we find that single men with sick parents are likely to delay retirement when they have siblings than when they do not have siblings.” Access to post-retirement health insurance makes both single men and women retire sooner. Moreover, the sum of the estimated coefficients on the health insurance variable and the interaction term of this variable with the parental care-need variable is always statistically significant and positive for men and women. This suggests that when parents are sick, having access to post-retirement health insurance facilitates earlier retirement. In results not displayed in Table 1.5, not surprisingly, retirement behavior is influenced by respondent age as well as health status. Transition into retirement is delayed for single men with larger household income. Single women retire earlier if net non-housing assets are larger. Men tend to retire sooner if they have a combination of defined benefit and defined contribution pension plans compared to when they do not have any pension enrollment. Defined benefit pension plans delay single women’s retirement.” 5.2 Results for Married or Partnered Individuals For couples’ estimations, Table 1.6 displays the coefficient estimates for the potential familial care-need variables and the sibling related variables. Table 1.7 presents the estimates for the health insurance and spousal employment variables. Estimation of the retirement model for couples considers potential family obligations from parents, parents-in-law, and the spouse/ partner. There appears to be no statistically significant evidence that married men and women retire sooner when a parent or a parent- in-law potentially needs care.28 Neither does it appear that married men and women retire sooner if their spouses are in need of care. On the contrary, individuals seem to delay 26Estimation of the model with the alternative retirement variable shows that when parents need care, women with siblings are likely to retire sooner than women without any siblings. 27We also estimate the retirement model defining the at risk sample to consist only of those working in the previous period, i.e., excluding those who were unemployed. In those specifications we additionally include an indicator for whether the individual was reported to be self-employed in the job held last period. We do this since it is probable that self- employment allows individuals more flexibility with their time allocation to competing needs. We do not find any evidence that self-employed non-coupled individuals retire any differently than non—self-employed individuals when faced with potential caregiving obligations. 28In fact, there is some evidence that for certain parental care-need and marital status, women might delay retirement; these delaying effects are significant for more parental vari- ables if we use the self—defined retirement variable than the retirement variable based on the current labor force status question. 14 retirement for particular spousal health events. For instance, wives whose husbands have activity limitations, and husbands whose wives have had experienced a severe or a chronic health condition, are likely to postpone retirement. For women, the result is consistent with Pozzebon and Mitchell’s (1989) finding that working women with a spouse in poor health tend to delay retirement. There is no significant effect of spouse’s recent health shocks on individual’s retirement timing, which is in line with Coile’s (2004) results. Like single men and women, married men and women retire earlier if they have Retiree health insurance, Medicare or other health coverage (RHI-M). Taking into account the esti— mated coefficients on the interaction variables with RHI-M, we find that married men and women with sick parents who have RHI—M are significantly more likely to retire early than those who do not have RHI—M. Similarly, people with sick spouses who have RHI-M are significantly likely to retire sooner than those who do not have RHI—M. Married men ap- pear more likely to retire early when their spouses are Medicare or retiree health insurance (SRHI-M) eligible. Also, there is some evidence that married men may be delaying retire- ment if their wives are covered by the men’s employer-provided health plans. Women delay retirement if the husbands are covered by women’s employer-provided health insurance, even when the husbands have their own retiree health insurance coverage. Conversely, if wives are eligible for retiree health insurance coverage (SRHI—M), men retire early even if spouses are covered by the men’s employer-provided health insurances. We find men and women retiring sooner if the spouse is not working. Thus, there is evi- dence for complementarity of leisure for married couples.29 But the sum of the coefficients on the interaction term Spouse not working at present*Spouse has new chronic or severe health condition and the spousal sickness variable does not reveal that spousal complementarity of leisure is stronger when a spouse is sick. In other words, individuals do not retire sooner when non-working spouses are ill compared to when they are healthy. Siblings or siblings- in-law do not affect retirement behavior in general. When husbands potentially need care, married women with siblings~in-law retire sooner than women without any sibling-in-law —— a result that contradicts the role of siblings as alternate caregivers. Among a few of the other findings, the higher the level of total household income, the 29Coile (2004) also reports evidence for a significant complementarity of leisure effect for men. 15 more likely married men and women are to delay retirement. Higher non-housing assets make men retire sooner. Individuals are likely to delay retirement if they have defined benefit pension enrollment. Own medical conditions precipitate retirement.30 6 Summary and Concluding Remarks In this chapter we look at the influence of people’s potential caregiving roles on their retire- ment timing. The general conclusion from this study is that familial caregiving obligation is not a strong determinant of people’s early retirement behavior. While we do not find any major evidence that parental care-need is associated with individuals’ retirement tim- ing, it appears that potential spousal care-need has a delaying effect on people’s retirement. The finding that retiree health insurance has a substantial effect on increasing the early retirement probability corresponds to the previous literature on the effects of retiree health insurance on retirement timing.31 What we additionally find is that individuals who have parents or spouses in need of care are more likely to retire early if they have access to retiree health insurances. Therefore, potentially losing employer-sponsored current or retiree health insurance coverage in the instance of early retirement, particularly for those who are not yet Medicare age-eligible, possibly plays a significant role in deterring individuals from retiring sooner when faced with caregiving obligations. We should note a few caveats of this study. It is possible that the variables needed for defining potential care-need by family members could be improved in future data collec- tion, thus enabling a closer examination of this issue. Particularly, it would be interesting to have better indication of the degree of severity of various health conditions to obtain further conclusive evidence of the possible causality between caregiving and retirement tim- 30As in the non-coupled sample, we estimate the retirement model for couples defining the at risk sample to consist only of those working in the previous period, i.e., excluding those who were unemployed. The results are not affected in any notable way. In those specifications we additionally include an indicator for whether the individual was reported to be self-employed in the job held last period. Self-employed coupled individuals do not appear to retire any differently than non-self-employed individuals when faced with care-need by family members. 31For example, Karoly and Rogowski (1994) note that the availability of retiree health benefits increases the baseline probability of retiring by nearly 50 percent, while Gruber and Madrian (1995) find that a single year of continuation of retiree coverage increases the retirement hazards among persons aged 55—64 by about 20 percent. 16 ing. Moreover, it would be useful to have information on potential care-need arising from children. Finally, it should be emphasized that the literature on the determinants of retirement has emphasized the importance of future retirement income accumulation that comes from Social Security benefit formulas and pension structures. A central behavioral assumption in an economic model of retirement is that individuals decide whether to retire by assessing the financial benefit from delaying retirement against the loss of utility from forgone leisure. In that regard a major deficiency of our analysis is that we do not explicitly account for the financial incentives to retirement in the framework of a forward-looking economic model of retirement. Consequently, our findings in this paper should be considered as suggestive effects of potential familial obligations on the timing of retirement. 17 Table 1.1: Reported Reasons for Retirement Spend Forced Poor Time Want to Did Not Health with Do Other Like Family Thirhgs ' Work Age Percent in Each Age Group Citing Reason as Number Of Category Important in Retirement Observations 52-58 55.08 61.19 55.33 27.03 21.30 219 59-61 48.96 45.36 57.91 38.46 19.87 413 62-64 38.29 41.73 63.40 50.07 21.87 899 65-67 35.32 39.47 63.23 60.05 21.33 610 68-73 34.71 38.64 59.14 57.92 18.47 277 1. We observe 5009 retirement transitions in the sample out of 25020 observations (the sample before conditioning on non-missing parental and spousal careneed variables). Of that, we have responses on reasons for retirement from 2418 retirees after they make their first transition into retirement. In the HRS, each retiree is asked whether they felt that they were forced into retirement. In another set of questions respondents are asked whether any of the four criteria — poor health, spending time with family, wanting to do other things, not liking work — has been a reason for retirement. Each criterion is considered as a reason for retirement if it is deemed very, moderately or somewhat important in retirement by the respondent. Each retiree can report multiple reasons as important in retirement. Data Source: 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000, 2002 and 2004 waves of the Health and Retirement Study. W'eighted tabulations. l8 Table 2: Hours of Care Provided to Parents and Grandchildren (In Past Two Years) Care Hours to Parents Care Hours to Grandchildren Sample Conditional on At Risk of Providing Care and Non-Missing Reports of Care Hours All 185.63 (10.56) 303.18 (14.42) [n=3848] [n=6927] Male 86.94 (8.95) 94.00 (21.59) [n=1412] [n=968] Female 242.84 (15.74) 337.16 (16.34) [n=2436] [n=5959] Age 52-58 214.01 (31.38) 475.87 (63.55) [n=494] [n=619] Age 59-61 180.08 (17.83) 284.09 (30.05) [n=943] [n=1431] Age 62-64 175.64 (16.54) 307.06 (26.18) [n=1271] [n=2032] Age 65-67 175.85 (19.47) 298.36 (27.78) [n=792] [n=1795] Age 68-73 219.18 (60.90) 228.15 (33.54) [n=348] [n=1050] Sample Conditional on At Risk of Providing Care and Reporting Positive Care Hours All 600.27 (30.94) 1023.46 (44.83) [n=1190] [n=2052] Male 449.66 (39.34) 575.88 (125.78) [n=273] [n=158] Female 645.11 (38.29) 1060.80 (47.33) [n=917] [n=1894] Age 52-58 597.28 (79.97) 1146.16 (143.10) [n=177] [n=257] Age 59-61 520.91 (46.05) 998.84 (97.07) [n=326] [n=407] Age 62-64 584.39 (49.10) 998.30 (78.38) [n=382] [n=625] Age 65-67 624.55 (59.47) 1046.01 (89.27) (112223] [n=512] Age 68-73 930.18 (243.45) 954.43 (130.27) [n=82] [n=251] 1. Standard error of the mean reported in parentheses. 2. Sample size reported in brackets. 3. Care hours to parents include hours provided to either parents or parents-in-law for married/ partnered couples. 4. Care hours to parents include hours spent in helping parents with household chores, errands and basic personal activities. Data Source: 1998, 2000, 2002 and 2004 waves of the Health and Retirement Study. 5" 6. See page 5 footnote 8 for further discussion on the sample sizes used in this table. 19 .votomou 2 Hausa @628 “820 05 ..o owe 05 defied war»: 23 55 808 55 25.25%“: 5m .v use: 5 .28 :96 :30 205 so a“: DA Soc 98 DE 5:3 20 wcuao we“ weapon $548.3 .3 DUES“ 38% £23 35328“ mambo: on 9 votomou v.8 >05 c053 080 m0 vooz E Ba 25an .m B3983 1358a Raccoon co GOUSEOCE wfiwmmfiéoe co Weepfieonu 2 0358 05 flan—63:3: .8358 -coc “om .Bflrefiucuuam « .5 Scuba « 356 no 2592585 @8938 Raccoon wE8Eéoc co Reoufica 2 0358 65 .8358 “om .N .7“ venom 2530a 06 5 p058 meta; you no 1325256 U venom 8 “205052 95 25288“ 05 we “deacon 2 Ease: EoEoupom A 20 88 8.8 88 -- -- 888 808820 65 do 6mm- 28 8.8 8.8 8.8 8.8 a? 2.2 8.2 8.2 8.8 8.8 was: 86888.8 82 23 88 8:. 88 68 6188 56o? 88 88 88 -- -- Essa €088.20 66 do 68. 8.8 8.8 8.8 8.8 8. 8 68.... :2 8.2 88 8.8. 8.2 EST 868888 88 22 88 82 82. 6N8 2988 5: mac—038303 @2950 88 88 88 -- -- 865 2808820 2: do 63 8.8 8.8 2.8 R8 8.8 68.4 8.2 8.8 2.2 88 8.8. Ema: E68668 88 8... 88 88 82 68 6388 8:88 R8 88 88 -- -- .55 808820 as do a? 8.8 8.8 8.8 8.8 8. 8 63 8.2 8.8 8.2 88 8 28 Has: 888882 o2 2 OS 88 8: 68 6188 :62 Q 8 6 Q 8 , @2888: 8380-82 080 we 3oz NDSU m0 30H. Sagan E 82 ESE @662 5 868m 258m wewpfl wemcfi 30539 888 was: 80 as: E as? 6388 oz .28 6188 E... as? 288 3:08am winch/H.030 was MEZA oh. «commom 53? Wax—«Nam Evacuated an.“ 035.5 585%“ 25.3753 quwwuB Exam 5050.5“; v.8 5183 oi 30 3:3 VQON wad NOON .OOON £82 .303 €02 .Noe “825m Sufi .3 6056.50 ~23; 055m 5 05030 E52923 550m. 25 Eco 28.; 825% 80:3 95% 05 2:5 50683220 25. .m .8298 618: 950033 1.25% 05 8953 05 «Ed 05 a9 05 9 80%»: £5 2555800 5.88; 55858 31:: 8 5096:8me 05 085 E mun—022: noun 5: 2E woow 28% ~38: 8.025% .5 bowuuau 3F .v. don—NH 22228 0082.pr 05 8 new: 332.2; 1.25% 545 was $0.538 EEBOA 125% do COUEEEE $525.25: :0 1:25.500 2 2958 2.5. .m 2.25% 2“ 52.3503 E5553 0.8 325% 55.. 205.25 ”2253.55 505qu was vow—.85 01205 81:00 .N A-“ ~5ch 25165 06 E “558 MERE 5: c0 15206.50 u @025 8 52558 95 25.2285 2.: 2. 0265 2 ES“; 5qu50% A 3.3 3.3 NN.m3 N83 oN.m3 3.3 053 2N3 NW3 uw< Mumsomm 3.3 made 3.3 wwdo ow.3 3.0m wN.3 $.03 8.3 uw< $.NN dew mde 3.3 SAN 3.3 3odN 3.3 and“ Edna: EuEuEum MH : mNcb moo“ mhho am 2‘ NmoH N. HON comm wwww vim “Vacuum 20:53 bowm omfim :uwm VMNm ONdm vmfim wwwm mNHm omNm um< Mumnomm NW3 9&3 wo.3 wm.3 NTNO $.03 mh.3 mm.3 9‘3 uw< RNN 3.2 No.3 3.3 3.8 wvfiw aNdH dew and“ $882 5qu2qu 8: 88 82 88 2.8 8.8 8: 88 :8 0N8 0368 :02 av 83 S 8 @ E 6 Q 8 28> £885 38> N :3 E ..anmaou An? N 882 E 0803 .2 05025 $500 50 525$me 050$ . Z \3551 \uugum vcoufiaou 50> 5 H262 AQ< \13553 E 03F QEOEU m50m 5 50:00me «81353.55 u< 83 OZ 3: 5 Sum zoom 52 854 u< \Egum OZ “Rm ~38: 6:83 55:00 025mm 025mm 3: 025mm 33 025mm 83 025mm 33 025mm Momdomm Momsomm .5 038mm 515m 350mm 0 H. “commum 53? Etuauam 2.205050% #4 28$. 21 33 3: $3 32 mm? 82 mm? 8: 889530 €89 €89 €89 €89 €89 68.9 $99 $89 88.8 88.8 A8.8 88.8- 88.8 88.8 88.8 38.8 8328 £8; 550 8 38902 .8335 fifidofl ovufiomuwouwu m0 fiqu 5 503 HO UNQ HO EOE €89 $8.9 €89 €89 €89 €89 €89 88.9 .332. 33H... 1&5... ..iwmfio £55.: 334.: 3&36 3&36 owfigg fifidofi uufiuo HO Uudummvuz .UUCNHDmGM r3133 ovuflum €89 28.9 68.9 28.9 83 .338- 83 +3.... @823 3528 mo 38 a £8 8 Ed 8 So: 989 €89 $8.9 €89 28.8- 888. 08.8- A0.8.8. 382?, mmI 63.9 38.9 €89 $2.9 $3.3. $8.8 +38- 988 28 80 Bug 5 E“ 62833 9 BEE 33:52 38.9 €89 €89 889 +83. +8.3. 98.8. 3.2.... 28 8o 38 5 805 mo 25 En BEE Ba Ba 80: €89 83.9 €89 €89 98.8. 38 98.8 888 28 80 BE 5 805 mo £8 Ea BEE RD Ed :82 .3 UHNU m0 @006 Gm USN mung—“Gag VNQ\EOE €89 €89 €89 €89 m 8.8 98.8 388 N88 838: 38.8 was =< €89 €29 €89 68.9 888.. 33 88.8 88.8 88 mo Bus 5 £8. 8 Ba 8 602 :89 $89 98.9 €89 88.8 :98- 88.8 :88- 2% £8 8 ED 8 so: Congo? Caz EEO? ~82 5.8089 =02 Cuzco? Caz mofiatfiw “covaomowcm #9 +6 #9 +9 9 6 9 9 Amcoumusd £93m 35m .533 38.26 wanD BSMUD “5889.6 8% 363— wcFaI “OZ :0 Raouacou com—Beau. «58053— 253339: wean—00:82 mo mGOEmSBH. 2580.53“ :o 2502 v.30 Havana 13:08.— .«o muoobm "m.“ 0355 22 00308; z8830 .80» >033 .«0 00m 05 318» 000 660930 00880 05 3 000008 00>00 £83 0030me 000 00000>%\0008«m0mv 3508? 300% 003000-000 £03803 >880? 00000800 $003.80 800 8 33056 000 00008—08 £0080000 F300: @xobm 000 .803000 0000; £00800 000>0m «000 0080308 iflwofionufim 00m £88000 .8830 w08 $000380 683000 00076 800.80 wcumnfi 000 300 .0wd w.000v00%00 00m $3089» >880? ,0w80>00 006000 .«0 89$ 00“ 83805, x8800 .30me 98303000 1300 .8088 00 08008 208030: H800 08000 092 E0: 38 0% 80¢ $8800 “000 000208 3030090 0080 000000 w8>m 00 3 83083 @0030 p.0 00m 05 00.« bowfiau 00880 05. ._. 00000 303000 05 300 00.800 w8>8 000 00 R000€000 @0000 080 08 >3 $8000 000000080 05 .t g 00 3000 05083 8080 a 8 00> 0083* w8>am 002 00 000080080 000608? 8080800M 0308? 000000000 05. xx; 00 0080.08me i. mo\om 00 “caumafi * ”$2 00 “caumfiwmm + 003500000 8 $0000 vuawcfim 0850M 00000000 000 8000890 05000 80¢ 800m“? fi8w§2 flung—BU m2! £an 23 0.8.9 0.8.9 29¢ 23 28 0o 38 5 Eng “‘0 503 was @UENE Bauncmumuwa mud-0 30767802 uO UHNU m0 UUUG Gm USN VUENECD BS-CTU«Q\3£-CTEOZ 95.9 38.9 89o- oood 3:8: 32-0-3500 was: 3 839 9.8.9 0.8.9 9.8.9 0.8.0. :99 89c 89¢. 28 00 BE 5 08 8 32-0-20 8 Ewe-EOE 05.9 . 08.9 089 0.8.9 0 So- 89o 29o- 89o 2% £8 8 32-5-20 8 32.5.88 03.9 08.9 .33.? owed 0000 .00 0000 8 000 00083303 00 000008 0mQ\802 03.9 3.99 mMOdn OmOdn 0.23 .«O “000G Gm 805 wO UGO «06.0 100308 Una «VG-m EOE 089 0.8.9 VMOd: wMOd 0.80 wO Uuuc CM 806 «#0 £003 mug “gun-08 @«Q 360 802 HO 0000 m0 @005 Cm mud-m «001.00% @0Q\EOE 05.9 9.5.9 83. $90 023; ”Sea was: i. 93.9 38.9 98.9 08.9 Sod- wmod- 39¢- Rod 28 00 Bus 5 £8 8 80 8 :52 35.9 959 A299 989 :9? 59¢. was- 89o- 2% £8 8 Ba 8 so: 0080 b? 002 0080 b? 002 0080 b? 002 m05000> 0000009005 9 9 ..9 ..0 0 9 9.00.5000 £09m 0000”“ 0000A 000000 w8mD 000003 000800006 00% 00000M m8>mI 002 00 R008000U 000608H. 000800.00m «0303?: 02030 .«0 mdSflmG—EH. 0.008300% 00 0000802 >080”— >£ 00002 0.80 Rtuouom .00 300mmm— 6.“ 030k. 24 68.9 08.9 88.8 888 @088 8: U3.8% 88.9 08.9 Bod 000.0 @3536 3100000 .00 0000 00 500 00 0mQ .8 EOE 689 0.89 28.8- 88.8 @888 8: 08.9 38.9 88.9 38.9 08.9 689 N88- mood 88.8- 88.8 88.8. 28.8 88 8 B8 a £8 8 32-0-80 00 30—IGTEOEVwGOUmUGOU UmGOHSU\0-0>0m 30G m0£ 0m30mm $8.9 38.9 68.9 08.9 98.9 089 +358. 888 +888. 88.8 +898. 888 28 0o 88 a 08 8 UOQ .«0 802*GOUEGOU UGOG£0\0G0>0w 30G w0£ 0msomm 9.8.9 0.8.9 98.9 08.9 98.9 08.9 888. 888- +088- 88.8- 388. 888- 880.8: .09.. 8o 82 0 8; 88% 0 8.9 08.9 08.9 08.9 0 8.9 08.9 888- 88.8- 888- 88.8- 88.8- $8.... 8.288 383 a 08 88 U89% 0 8.9 0 8.9 08.9 0 5.9 0 8.9 08.9 88.8- +888- 88.8- 38.8- 88.8- +888- 8288 888 a 88 8; 88% 88.9 08.9 98.9 98.9 08.9 08.9 .888 88.8- 8.8 88.8. 88.8 A8.8. 8888 888888 38 WE 88% 88.9 08.9 :88 988 88 0o 88 00 000 00008503 9 000.080 BS-000«D\B£-0TEOE $8.9 08.9 88.8- 88.8 38 0o 88 5 E05 MO 0G0 0G0 @0908 B0~n5nUOQ fiG0 307G780: G050? G02 G080? G02 G080? G02 m0—£0C0> uG0—0G0Q01GH 9 6 +8 .06 0 9 82880 8.0 280- 25 .mufiaig >556 :3» >033 mo How 05 SSE wad .Abowouau notice 05 3 588m 830% 55 BEE: FEB Susanna “comp“ 350mm :5 BEE: we“ wouogmmv mofiutg £58m Bins .mofimcg @556 c0985? .«0 Hum $0.238“ 38v 5 5165.6 5m ~98qu .mcoEwGOU 518; 39% v5 .8039.” two: 565$ 826m 98 Amado—ACE Rumwofiosukflmm ER @555 633.6 ms: .muuonfifi .3385 @0016 PEPE“. @536 we“ Bu: 6% 130% am.“ meovcommfl 5w 83.32; >E§v .uwfigonv commcom .«o 8% 5w mufiacg >EE~6 .883 mammsoséoc ~39 Juana 3 0885 205830: 139 .flOtom amm— Eo: L2 05 80¢ wwceuwo £38m suck/fie: 1350mm .5.“ “88.65 Ca .owSu>0u 518: 850 8 83:52 625235 518: 358 130% v5“ :30 5a 83am»? >E§v 93 ”8a 33:05 magnum“: 350 .v .AB«_-E-E8«& wary: 0: 92a “dogma mg: 0: mm 353:3 Banana .«0 How 05 “Om fowouau BEEO 2F ... .m 62.5mm msorfia of EC: 3.58 mag: “cc :0 :EOUEGOU woven :8: 06 3 858 “595%“: 2: 3 fl 9 1370 013:; #353 « fl 3% waved wEZwI “OZ co Ecouficou coEmcfih EoEBflum 2&an Euflfiiufi BE. in. .o\o_ an EducEwG .1" ”Axum 2w 38¢?wa * 3&3 um Emumefi + .mowuficoumm E 9598 vaawcfim “950% .vutomou Ba 809358 “Boa 80¢ 88:0 13%ng A Chow whmw vmow vovw chow wbmw meetmtomfio $8.9 $3.9 Bed 83 gain was umsommvwcoufics uEOEU\Bu>um Bu: was 350mm 28.9 33.9 Nmod mood @wcaflm was omnommuwoumu mo Boa E 503 Ho BSéfifiaQ Ho 33-5-802 580? 52 5803 52 6V Amv ... Avv ._. A0 60:59:60 64 o—nah. 5803 S 52 ‘ moianflw «cuwcomovcm 8 26 —:_uCUuCn— MC 36.3530 0—: Cm ”...—5.3m uC.u—C>C_C~Cw~ Eviccm 52a 99292.0 0023.255: fizfiumko EUDEQ ..h.~ DEER. 5289 50.505 05 m5: 2888 @523 5c :0 1252588 *5qu H8: 8% .3 888 585088 05 E H 8 15—8 0388., 5.83 8 mm 8% 880m @8163 5 Z .5 idea—850 50288.2. 50:883— 0388.) 5350938 83. .N .9: a .588 ...... 88m 8 “Gnomemm ... 882 8 “gumawww + 8085889 5 888 88—53...“ 825% 808098 88 2528588 “305 Set 889.8 1.85982 3.3 mhmo chow mhmw 5088830 $89 #89 N56- mmod 8858: ~38: 83>on 8.53:8 $828088 .3 @888 mm 8509988602 .5 8:835 680: 858 was 830mm 88.9 98.9 v5.0- +39? 85885 61.0: @8305 8.55:8 88285988 .3 @888 mm omsomw A899 2 8.9 306 ......mmcé 08.888 518: 8:5 5 88:82 .8552: 518: 8.58 was vasomm $8.9 $8.9 wood “$888 ~28: 8:5 .5 88:82 wood .8888": ~38: 088m...cou%:8 8588\88bm Bu: 8: owsomm 98.9 9.8.9 mmod- 098850 5:8: 8:5 .5 88:82 wad .8859: 5:8: 088m...88 .5 v8: 5 A53 5 RD .5 :52 38.9 38.9 ......Ebd ......wwod “$888 .28: 8:5 5 88:82 .8852: «28: 088% 9.8.9 889 owed- mmod matte? 5: umsomm*cou:58 0508—8888 38 was owsomm A899 A899 3.3%.: ......wacé 5889 um way—53 5c omsomm 8:5? 82 850.3 ‘82 8388.; “8280825“ 8 5 S 3 27 @5880 258m 85m .583 58.50 wEmD wucmoQ 2888qu 8% @8th wcréz 52 co ficowficoU c0288.". 5058.532 wig—writs wean—GU .5 mucflmmcauh 508833“ .5 88—502 @«m .3 882 080 38585 .5 88.50 05 5 858m EoEBn—Em— Emu—cam can 098950 85885 .28: .5 88am up.“ oEwH. uF-nuuba-..——- a. flu-‘5‘ d.u-.,-l-o ...... —- 1.03:3:an has 0—55.? .mofiacg 8098239: 350 05 mo 8088.888 « 80m 0 033. 8 v 802 oum .N GED—CU o 035. 8 33883 of 32m $5 cowmmuwwfi 08$ 05 80d 8388 05 3.598 ANV GEEOU BULB Av 88“ N 88208 5803 88 53:85 fiutoauu Ba 8388 806508 80:? 87383 .8088?“ 03» as... 33 a cEBOU 8 commmouwe 2.? mm 08% 2t wafirfigo £83 cowmmoumou 880»wa « 80m. 83883 St 82w m 88.300 .— 88:00 0 03¢? 8 83888 05 82m $5 commmflwou 08$ 05 80¢ 3158 ufi 3898 a 88300 H.268”. 5 cash 28 .xwx§$fi$\ 030% 05 808,00 008838 510: 808308 8080180 $128288 05 805083 80 808888.88 08 wfiwguxm .8 203000838 .80858030 be: .088 mmmow 0.8“ 80803 .088 808 80.« m0fim 018$ 05 608310 8880. 8080.808 808238.28 05 wEms 8080808 0.508 03 8055 .m 203000838 .8080? 88m 808 80“. 80898030 >3 2 88¢ Sumo“ "80838.0 888% 80808808 808088.88 05 w8m8 880808.808 08:08 03 8083 80800.28 08“ Sum 088.8 08H. 880885 9:.— 05 8. 808387 888m 38 880880 08 388 808.808 808080m .N 880856 mm: voom 88¢ .Noomndoom dog dog .303 £02 05 808.8 502800888 $803308? econ 88a .omE. .5? 4%; .Nfivw .Nfiww .wmho A 88.8 83 0888 Not 888 m 88 8 8835.82 8.85888 8826 05:8 8 83 $8 .88 2238: 3880-82 8 88.8 88 .8 8.3 83 88.8 882 88.88-82 38% s0 88250 83388 580: 808168 8 0\0MO.G© Chow o\0ON.©w Whmw o\0ON.NO Vmth hwcmwwwEIGOZ GOUNEOwCH Rmsomm USN .Bflacmnucpflwm JCUHNQ mm o88.8 88 88.8 88 88.8 888 88386-82 888888 808880 88.5.55 8 05:8 8 88.8 88 88.8 .88 88.8 08: 05388-82 8.8883 3826 33.5.0808 Ea 05:8 8 88.8 88 88.8 $8 88.8 802 8 .mwséeeoz 888888 3826 33-5-0888 8 88.8 88 88.8 :8 88.8 88: 0 8838.82 88883 80880 0588 8 88.8 88 83.8 E8 888 88: vwcaméeoz 88080 $50 a... 83889 30880 8.8on 8 $8 $8 888 223.68 3.880 8 88.8 288 988.3 28: 88.8 8.8m «8.5832220 ED808808 8886-82 8 88.? 888 88.3 88: 88.? 808. Nausea; 95 262 Em 032 328530 86208 88.? 888 88.3 88.8 88$ 88 0:8 68833 a 8385 88808 82 :5 058388 mo 0.88 0< 8 83$ 8:; 88.3 888 8 8.3 898 086qu8 mo 0.88 E 8 88.8 888. 88. 5 82m 83.8 28% 8850 $2328 2,8828 038 0&3 “<8 8 8.8 888 888 N88. 88.8 888 8380 8-25.0, “oz 8 «2.2.. mag anFm “@030E088H 2830.888: tOLOU mMI 03mw=m0w< w0 803882 130M. 0:888 032 8 880880 80800—0m flaam #44 038k. 08888 29 1.0..CICCU —.<.~ u._£=.H. 2038008838 080886080 oaov 888 who“ 03 80803 «.88 808 80.8 88m. 0388 05 80.8887 88% 80808008 "008098-88 05 w8m8 880808.808 088-808 03 80:? 89:88“ 8880898 05 80m 8830800 88% 0388 of; .mono 8 08m 0388 08 £83..” 8.8«8 w8m: 35883 8008008 80an .«0 80m 08 80m .8083 18.38 8880.80 3 888008080 008 0—0 :88 83883 8008083 88088 m0 00m 08 88 0:“ 38m 0383 .30>800%08 $808308? vmao “08¢ NE. 08“ 80803 88a 808 80.8 «08m 0188 05 80.8.8010 883 80808008 80080880888 05 w8w8 8080808 0580—0 03 82$? 898488 80880898 08 80.8 0830—08 888 0888 0.3. 8080 :03 08 80888 08“ 3808.8 808 8083 088 .80 .0008 8 8 38-8-8030 80 80.88. 888 8080:? 80 888880-88 w8mm8 00 030 8 80.808808 05.- .vom: 8 08m 0388.. 05 .885 88.38 w8m8 33883 8008088 38-8-8080 .80 00m 08 80.8 mmww: 8 08m 0888 08 .888 18.88 w8m8 8388; 8008030 80.88 .80 00m 08 80m .883 18888 880.88 83 €3.88 “.08 0—0 888 35888 8008080 38-8880880580an .80 00m 08 80.8 0am 88m 018$ .8880. 8008 0880 .8“ 888m w8>= 8803a 803 08808 83888 @008 0.30 B«_-8-880§m\80§m 328080 32 oz“..- 30 0.07—5.23? kc motmta~gaEEZm ..Nééx 2:35 33.3 gamma 8.3 33.3 8.8 $3 Seamus m3 :3 Nwdfi $8 3.8 No.3 oo.mm Kém 88.2 chow HZ 8.3 pawns NE 88 3.33 3.3 swans 8.8 mm.» 2.: $6 oofim 3.8 Nowm mmdm mmwfi whmw HZ $3 @33ch 33.3 3.3 303 5‘6 ofiwm Nm.mm vwdm mmmv-I-Z 83 cotucv $3 $3 OW: No.5 08mm motnz 303383> 80880 0Q 030 .80 8008 8 883 8038803 9 80838 33_-8-83Q\33_-8-802 0.30 00 8008 8 808 .80 080 883 80838 33T8-83Q 883 3388-802 030 .8 8008 8 808 883 808.38 3388-83Q 883 3388-802 80 030 .«0 8008 8 883 8083888 33_-8-83Q\33_-8-802 8.8308 3388-38038 w8>= =< 030 .80 8008 8 883 80388083 08 80838 83Q\802 030 .80 8008 8 808 .«0 080 883 80838 83D 883 802 030 00 8008 8 808 .80 808 883 808.38 83C 883 802 80 030 .80 8008 8 883 808.3888 83Q\802 882308 38038 w8>= =< 030 00 8008 8 808 80 3388-830 80 3378-802 083 808 80 33_-8-83Q 80 3388-802 030 00 8008 8 808 80 83D 80 802 083 808 80 83C 80 802 3835 8080832 8080 0M-r0m 833 808-«0Q 808080 80> 8080M m8>3I 82 80 38088800 808833. 8080.80m 80.83080 883m 008m 8838 80.880 w833 808-«0Q 8080806 80> 8080M w8>3I 82 80 88088800 8088838. 8080.888 8080 B 802 8080 B 802 E 6 S 8 8&8 803800 0383 803800-802 303835 .«0 308835 b3888m ”add 033R. 31 casctccu 34.. 023k 3033838» 80880 088m wV.©m mVHm ..I II 0wdu0>00 £5803 H050 HO 0.880602 608.855 5103 00.8.0.“ wmfi 0m50mm HNdm MM.O© bOfiO NGJO 0WNu0>OU 57305 H050 HO 0HNO€02 .0uddufimfim 6132* 00830.”— amwimzv 6.8.5.0 9.88330 8.8 83330 8.33.83... 2.33.33 8.5.33 2.3.33 @883 383-8% 8 383 3882-83 85.3 8.8me 8.8830 8.8330 A2823: 838.3 2033.? 3.28.3 8.83.3 . 88:03 8.83-888 8 8888 8 2:88 8238; 88.3 6.0333 9.838 9.830 6.3830 333.33 8.88.33 $83.8 $38.33 888% 88-8.8 33 323 88 8 22 3 23 853 ,0ch88 5.3 mwfv .i I 380308 w88803 008 0825 $.83 8.33 833 2.33 €828 :8 B82880 8 880 30828 :8 38015.88 3? owVw N~.m H NOdH wV.w~ 380% N uwam 05 S GOflmuCOU 0H0>0m HO 2.60.83 @0mOGwNM—u 3302 8.3 3: 3.8 o; 83888 88 25 :32 a am 8.83 3.33 33.3 33.3 88338 225... 3 3E 3: $.33 88:. 8.33 8.0% 808:8 88:8 3 3E 3: .033 8.33 -- -- 888... WE 38% 8.33 2.88 2.8 3.5 ”3888 a: 830 8.30 mwdc mo.wm .. I A830; 80 0w3 3.03895 8330 $3.0 Si 83.0 3. 3 $8 8. S S. S 08.8 so .83 oi: Om.m~ u. u- 3.30% N 538 08 8 8088800 080>0w 80 080.80 308 3; 0380mm co. 3 N53 .. n. 80838.88 4% 080 332 3 3: 0380mm mwém oodfi .. n. 8088800 080>0m 3 838 338 0826 $60 N98 .. .. 8088800 0880.80 3 838 3: 0380mm 8080 3 802 8080 b? 802 E 8 Q 8 0883 803800 0~m83m 8088800802 8088800 NJ: 033R. 32 cozccccc ~.<.F 023,—. .80Ewm03 083 383088 =< 30308880030 88 80000000 003 38083308 8038830m 33:08 835-030» E 083 3088mm 03=0Q 80808808 03880050 $08.5 0800000 5 083 38038888 =< (\im'v'm' .8308 038580.80 $0888 chow 0303 0—9833 .3 8EBOU ”80008 03850280 33288 wnmw 083 018833 m 888200 ”80008 03850050 330880 Mmmv 037. 01533 N 88300 ”80008 038.3050 301.3 Net 0wa 01833 ~ 888200 A 33 23 $3 .. .. 320528 VM.O 0M.O II II 8m—uc0m0unw «C0mfiw 0mdomw “BL UOEw: 8.09 2.00 .. .. 0803088 030% :83 808832 .. .. B3... 3333 3030339 .. -- in? 33.3 38.86%.38303 -- -- 333 33.30 3252 0.62 $30 :33 3.83 53.3 030:8 00 083 3 5:3 go: 03.: 33.: 8.3 5.2 030:8 Meow 33.8. 33.3.3 33.0.3 $.33 833383 88,0. 3308 S. 8.3 33.3.3 3333 33.0.3 8333033 320... £32 56 380 33.3 $3 83 333 833888 383% 35 03083 323% 00 8325800 3338 3338 3338 3338 53 8353 833388 305300 33.03 3333 $33 3330 53 c2803 0322 38300 33333 53mg nmdm :wm .... u. 0083.333 .830: 8088680 80>0EE0 3.0808800308 83 88260 38 umsomm 303383, 080880 088m 80880? 802 80880? 802 33 30 S 8 £983 80380U 0383 803800802 80:88:00 NJ: 033k. References [1] Blau, David M. 1998. “Labor Force Dynamics of Older Married Couples.” Journal of Labor Economics; Vol. 16: pp. 595-629. [2] Coile, Courtney C. 2004. “Health Shocks and Couples" Labor Supply Decisions.” NBER Working Paper No. w10810. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. [3] Department of Health and Human Services. 1998. Informal Caregiving Compassion in Action. Washington DC. DHHS: Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. [4] Dentinger, Emma and Martin E. Clarkberg. 2002. “Informal Caregiving and Retire- ment Timing Among Men and Women: Gender and Caregiving Relationships in Late Midlife.” Journal of Family Issues; Vol. 23 No. 7: pp. 857-879. [5] Ettner, Susan L. 1995. “The Impact of ‘Parent Care’ on Female Labor Supply Deci- sions.” Demography; Vol. 32, No. 1: pp. 63-80. [6] Gibeau, Janice R. N. and Jean W. Anastas. 1989. “Breadwinners and Caregivers: In- terviews With Working Women.” Journal of Gerontological Work; Vol. 14(1-2): pp. 19-40. [7] Corey, Kevin M., Robert W. Rice and Gary C. Brice. 1992. “The Prevalence of Elder Care Responsibilities Among the Work Force Population.” Research on Aging; Vol. 14(3): pp. 399-418. [8] Gruber, Jonathan and Brigitte C. Madrian. 1995. “Health-Insurance Availability and the Retirement Decision.” The American Economic Review; Vol. 85, No. 4: pp. 938-948. [9] Hayward, Mark D, Samantha Friedman, and Hsinmu Chen. 1998. “Career Trajectories and Older Men’s Retirement.” Journal of Gerontology: Social Sciences; Vol. 53B: pp. 891-8103. [10] Hurd, Michael D. 1990. “The Joint Retirement Decision of Husbands and Wives.” In Davis A. Wise edited Issues in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. [11] Johnson, Richard W. and Melissa Favreault. 2001. “Retiring Together or Working Alone: The Impact of Spousal Employment and Disability on Retirement Decisions.” Center for Retirement Research Working Paper No. 2001-01. [12] Karoly, Lynn A. and Jeannette A. Rogowski. 1994. “The Effects of Access to Post— Retirement Health Insurance on the Decision to Retire Early.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review; Vol. 48: pp. 103-123. [13] Lumsdaine, Robin L. and Olivia S. Mitchell. 1999. “New Developments in the Economic Analysis of Retirement.” In Orley Ashenfelter and David Card edited Handbook of Labor Economics; Vol. 3: Elsevier Science. [14] Lumsdaine, Robin L., James H. Stock, and David A. Wise. 1990. “Efficient Windows and Labor Force Reduction.” Journal of Public Economics; Vol. 43(2): pp. 131-159. 34 [15] Pavalko, Eliza K. and Julie E. Artis. 1997. “Women’s Caregiving and Paid Work: Causal Relationships in Late Midlife.” Journals of Gerontology; Vol. 52B: pp. 8170-8179. [16] Pavalko, Eliza K. and Kathryn A. Henderson. 2006. “Combining Care Work and Paid Work: Do Workplace Policies Make a Difference?” Research on Aging; Vol. 28(3): pp. 359-374. [17] Pienta, Amy M. 1997. “Older Couples: An Examination of Health and Retirement within the Context of the Family.” Penn State University Population Program Working Paper No. 97-03. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University. [18] Pienta, Amy. M. 2003. “Partners in Marriage: An Analysis of Husbands’ and Wives’ Retirement Behavior.” Journal of Applied Gerontology; Vol. 22: pp. 340-358. [19] Pozzebon, Silvana and Olivia S. Mitchell. 1989. “Married Women’s Retirement Behav- ior.” Joutnal of Population Economics; Vol. 2(1): pp. 39-53. [20] Raymo, James M. and Megan M. Sweeney. 2006. “Work-Family Conflict and Retirement Preferences.” Journal of Gerontology; Vol. 61B, No. 3: pp. 8161-8169. [21] St.Clair, Patricia, Darlene Blake, Delia Bugliari, Sandy Chien, Orla Hayden, Michael Hurd, Serhii Ilchuk, Fuan-Yue Kung, Angela Miu, Constantijn Panis, Philip Pantoja, Afshin Rastegar, Susann Rohwedder, Elizabeth Roth, Joanna Wedell, and Julie Zissi- mopoulos. 2006. RAND HRS Data Documentation: Version F. Labor and Population Program: RAND Center for the Study of Aging. [22] Szinovacz, Maximiliane E. and Stanley DeViney. 2000. “Marital Characteristics and Retirement Decisions.” Research on Aging: Vol. 22: pp. 470-498. [23] Szinovacz, Maximiliane E., Stanley DeViney, and Adam Davey. 2001. “Influences of Family Obligations and Relationships on Retirement: Variations by Gender, Race, and Marital Status.” Journal of Gerontology: Social Sciences: Vol. 56B: pp. 820-827. [24] Walker, David. 2002. “Long-Term Care: Aging Baby Boom Generation will Increase Demand and Burden on Federal and State Budgets.” United States General Accounting Office; Testimony before the Special Committee on Aging. United States Senate. March 21,2002. 35 Chapter 2 PREDICTABILITY OF RESIDENTIAL MOBILITY: EVIDENCE FROM THE HEALTH AND RETIREMENT STUDY 1 Introduction Expectations of future events play a prominent role in economic models of decision-making under uncertainty. Hurd and McGarry (1995) note that subjective expectations may deter- mine behavior, even if incorrect. This paper adds to the growing literature that assesses the potential usefulness of subjective expectation information in micro data. The key research question in this paper is: What do subjective expectations about moving tell us? Drawing on the longitudinal data from The Health and Retirement Study, we document the relationship between moving expectations and subsequent moving realizations among the United States population ages sixty-five and older. There has been an upsurge of interest in the policy debate with respect to the well being of the elderly population in the recent decades. Residential moving represents an important economic outcome variable that can involve a change of living arrangement as an independent household, with adult children or other unrelated persons, or in an institution. Engelhardt and Gruber (2006) note that changes in living arrangements are likely to be associated with changes in the level of care and assistance received by the elderly. Living arrangements additionally affect the elderly’s eligibility and transfer level for certain types of government assistance, such as, food stamps and supplemental Social Security (since these are determined by the income of the household, not of the individual). As such, it is important to know if the elderly are making mistakes in their predictions for future moving, which could have adverse consequences. 36 Some household surveys ask about subjective probabilities, and studies analyzing the validity of responses to these questions have found encouraging results.1 The Health and Retirement Study (HRS) asks respondents a number of expectational questions on matters such as survival to a target age, working beyond the normal retirement age, residential mobility, nursing home entry, job stability, receiving inheritances, and making bequests. Hurd and McGarry (1995, 2002) study survival expectations and conclude that the subjective survival probabilities are not simply an alternative measure to health status and that they predict mortality. Loughran, Panis, Hurd, and Reti (2001) and Haider and Stephens (2007) find that retirement expectations are strong predictors of retirement. Maestas (2007) studies the expectations of work during retirement and shows that unretirement is anticipated for the vast majority of those returning to work. Finally, Rohwedder and Kleinjans (2006) find that at the population level expectations about Social Security earnings are very consistent with realizations. Besides studies that use the HRS expectational variables, there have been a number of important studies on individual expectations about different events that exploit data sources other than the HRS, both from the United States and elsewhere.2 The results of these papers lend confidence that respondents on average understand the probability questions, and by and large the papers conclude that the expectations are fairly accurate predictors of the future event / outcome that they are supposed to characterize. As in studies on other expectations, we also find that the subjective probabilities of moving are very important in predicting future moving, even once demographic information known to be associated with the propensity to move is added to the analysis. Although this relationship is positive and monotone, the probabilities of moving rise much less than one-to- one with subjective probabilities. Still, information on expectations improves the accuracy of models of moving behavior most likely because it includes information about unobserved 1See Dominitz and Manski (1997) for a discussion of a history of subjective probability questions in survey data. 2Most notably, Bernheim extensively analyzes the responses from the Retirement History Survey (RHS) on age of expected retirement (1990) and expected Social Security benefits (1988; 1989). Dominitz and Manski (1997) analyze data on expected future income from the Survey of Economic Expectations (SEE), and Manski and Straub (2000) use workers’ subjec- tive expectations about job security from the same source. Das and Van Soest (11999, 2001) explore income expectations using data from the Dutch Socio-Economic Panel; appelli and Pistaferri (2000) look at expectations of nominal income growth using the Bank of Italy Survey of Household Income and Wealth; and Souleles (2002) examines expectations about respondents’ future financial position from the Michigan Consumer Sentiment Surveys. 37 tastes and individual circumstances. We find that moving is subjectively a low probability event, even for most movers. For a sizable fraction of movers — about 43% —— moving apparently represents an entirely unanticipated shock / event, because they report a subjective probability of zero. Individual responses of subjective probabilities contain considerable noise in the form of inordinate number of focal responses of “0”, “0.5”, and “1”. There is some indication that the response of “don’t know” is similar to a response of “0.5” in the subjective probabilities. Motivated by the observed relationship between the reported subjective probabilities and actual moving propensities, we put forward the hypothesis that when people are asked for a subjective probability they report the true probability conditional on available information, plus some random noise. We look at the proposed model’s implications regarding which pOpulation groups are better at predicting future residential moving. However, we fail to substantiate the hypothesis, and therefore, cannot conclusively identify individual charac- teristics associated with better forecasting. The outline of the remainder of the chapter is as follows. The next section describes the data used in this study. Section 3 characterizes the subjective moving probabilities and their correlates. Section 4 presents the descriptive relationship between moving expectations and subsequent residential moves. ,The same section also explores~ the role of subjective probabilities in economic models of residential mobility. Section 5 examines what people report when asked for the subjective probabilities, and also explores which groups are better at predicting. The paper closes with a conclusion in Section 6. 2 The Data We use data from The Health and Retirement Study (HRS). The HRS is a longitudinal biennial survey of the American population that had its first wave of interviews in 1992. The analysis draws on data from five survey years from 1998 to 2006 on individuals from four cohorts in the HRS: AHEAD (born between 1890—1923), CODA (born between 1924- 1930), HRS (born between 1931-1941), and War Babies (born between 1942-1947). The key question concerning moving expectation in the HRS is: 38 Now using the same scale as before where “0” is absolutely no chance and “100” means that it is absolutely certain, please tell me what you think are the chances that you will move in the next two years? (00-10—20——30—40—50—60—70—~80—90—100) Normalizing the responses to [0, 1] allows treating them as subjective probabilities of resi- dential mobility.3 The moving expectation question is asked to the respondents if either of the following conditions is met: (1) The respondent is at least 65 years of age, or (2) The respondent is giving a new interview (to the new interviewees the question is asked irrespective of age). In other words, if an individual is under age 65 and is a reinterview respondent, the moving expectation question is not asked. We investigate the predictability of moving for those ages 65 and older. The Health and Retirement Study over-sampled blacks, Hispanics, and Floridians, and therefore, throughout the analysis of this paper we use respondent-level sampling weights. Our sample design is motivated by the idea of studying moving behavior in relation to the subjective probabilities of moving elicited in the immediate prior survey wave. Therefore, to contribute an observa- tion to the sample, the respondent has to be part of at least two consecutive survey waves. For the number of years of data we consider, an individual can provide a maximum of four observations to the sample. Table A21 in the Appendix describes the sample construction steps. For the cohort and age-eligible respondents, we retain 61,688 observations. where we observe an individual in any two successive interview waves. Of this, 35,720 respondents are of 65 years of age or older. We have non-missing subjective probability responses for 31,541 of the 35,720 observations. We additionally have don’t know and refusal responses to the moving expectation question for another 762 observations not included in this 31,541 sample size. We observe moving transitions conditional on non-missing subjective moving 3The questions on both moving expectation and realization in the HRS are such that any changes in residences irrespective of the distance involved is taken into account; in other words, a residential move can be within the same city, or the same state, as well as out of the current city, or state, of residence. 39 probabilities for 7,725 individuals in 1998—2000, and for 7,536, 7,876, and 8,404 individuals, respectively, for the years 2000—2002, 2002—2004, and 2004—2006. Restricting the sample to non-missing data on other respondent and household variables we finally retain a sample of 29,584 observations, excluding 513 observations that have don’t know or refusal responses to the moving expectation question. Of the final sample, the number of moving transitions observed in the four transition years are 7,494, 6,987, 7,292, and 7,811. Table A22 in the Appendix gives the summary statistics for all the variables used in the analysis of this paper. 3 Moving Expectation and Its Correlates The distribution of individual subjective moving probabilities for all observations is presented in Figure 2.1 — Panel A. The figure indicates a heaping of responses most notably at 0, and also at 0.5 and 14, a pattern found previously for other HRS subjective probability measures (Lillard and Willis, 2001). It has been suggested previously in the literature that some of the bunching of responses could be due to cognition error or misunderstanding (Hurd and McGarry, 1995; Hurd, McFadden and Gan, 1998), or due to imprecision in beliefs about these probabilities (Lillard and Willis, 2001). Figure 2.1 also clearly displays that most individuals have a very low subjective probabil- ity of moving, with more than 60 percent reporting zero. The figure also indicates significant heterogeneity across individuals. To understand how much of the variation in subjective moving probabilities can be explained by observable characteristics, Ordinary Least Squares regressions of the probability variable on observable characteristics typically used in studies of residential move5 are reported in Table 2.1. In Column (1), the analysis controls for race, gender, education groups (with the group of high school graduates omitted), marital status, a quadratic in age, health status captured by two dummy variables for the numbers of doctor- diagnosed medical conditions (with no condition as the omitted category), ownership of home, labor force status represented by three dummy variables (with complete retirement as 4The response of “1” is contributed largely by those who actually move, as can be seen in Panel B, which plots the distributions of the subjective moving probabilities separately for movers and non-movers. 5To mention a few of the papers on moving behavior: Venti and Wise (1989, 1990, 2004 ; Feinstein (1996); Borch-Supan, McFadden and Schnabel (1996); Clark and Wolf (1992 ; Borch-Supan (1989, 1990). 40 the omitted category), number of children, household size, individual earnings, total house- hold income, net housing value, net non-housing financial wealth, and dummy variables for survey waves. While the F-test for overall significance of the model is significant at the 0.001 level, the R2 from this regression is only 0.03. Marriedand widowed people report lower probabilities of making a residential move compared to never married, separated, and di- vorced people. Subjective probabilities of moving increase with education. Home-ownership is negatively associated with moving expectations. Adverse health conditions increase sub- jective moving probabilities. While undoubtedly more observable characteristics could be added to explain more of the variation in moving probabilities, these results suggest that subjective probability reports are considerably idiosyncratic. In the next three columns, in addition to the variables that enter the regression presented in Column (1), we add expectations about other future events to explore what future expec- tations make moving subjectively a more probable event. For instance, we take into account the expectation about whether income would keep up with inflation in the next five years, the subjective probabilities of survival for another 5 to 15 years, and the expectations about leaving a bequest and receiving an inheritance. All these expectation variables are measured as subjective probabilities, and range between 0 and 1, inclusive. Life expectancy and sub- jective probabilities of moving are negatively correlated. It could be that because of the consumption value of housing, the longer people expect to live, the less they expect to make a residential move to potentially tap into housing equity. The expectation that income would keep up with inflation is also negatively associated with subjective probabilities of moving. It could imply that unless the elderly are threatened that their purchasing power is going to be impacted, they are unlikely to expect to move and alter housing consumption. The expecta- tion of receiving inheritances is positively associated with subjective probabilities of moving. Incidentally, the expectations about longer life, receiving inheritances, and income keeping up with inflation can all be considered as positive things in an individual’s life. Bassett and Lumsdaine (2001) find evidence of a common “systematic” component across an individual’s subjective responses for different questions that is unrelated to whether the specific question of interest bears a positive or a negative connotation. In contrast, we find that subjective moving probabilities are both positively and negatively associated with apparently positive 41 expectations in life. 4 The Predictive Power of the Subjective Probabilities of Moving ‘ 4.1 Relationship between Expectations and Realizations An initial examination of the data suggests that the subjective probability measure might have predictive power for forecasting residential mobility — on average, individuals who have not moved report a moving probability of about 12.8%; movers report 36.1%. Figure 2.1 — Panel B indicates that the subjective probability distribution for non-movers is heavily concentrated at very low probabilities and is highly skewed. In fact, the median subjective probability for non-movers is 0%, the 75th percentile is 10%, and the 90th percentile is 50%. For movers, the distribution is relatively more dispersed. Their median subjective probability is 20%, 75th percentile is 80%, and their 90th percentile is 100%. However, it is noteworthy that approximately 43% of the movers reported a 0% chance of future moving possibility. Thus, for a sizable fraction of the movers, moving apparently represents an unforeseen event. The direct relationship between the subjective moving probability and subsequent moves is shown in Figure 2.2 — Panels A and B. Panel A shows the relationship for all the survey waves pooled together; Panel B presents the relationship separately for the four waves of moving transitions. The dashed and dotted lines in the two panels give the fractions of individuals actually moving by their reported subjective probability. The plots in Figure 2.2 indicate that there is a positive relationship between the subjective probabilities and the incidence of moving. Most notably, there is at least a doubling of realized moving between those with a 80% subjective probability and those with a 100% subjective probability. These results are indicative of subjective probability’s predictive power. It is notable that the non-solid lines, representing the fraction of individuals actually moving by their subjective probability, look very similar across waves. However, the fact that the realization lines fall below the 45-degree line (except for those who report a zero probability) suggests that a substantial number of individuals in the sample tend to overstate their mobility probabilities. 42 For the entire sample population, the mean of subjective moving probabilities is 15.60% and the mean moving propensity is 12.12%. In other words, the sample average of the forecast errors (deviation between the actual moving outcome and the reported moving probability) is non-zero: overall, there is about a 29% over-prediction in the subjective probabilities.6 4.2 Economic Models of Residential Mobility Even though the predictions about residential mobility remain noticeably unfulfilled for almost the entire range of reported subjective probabilities, we do observe that the realization rate is increasing in the subjective probabilities. Naturally, if people can tell us something about their future moving through the subjective probabilities, then the predictions have the potential for improving modeling of moving behavior. As such, we can expect to find additional covariation between actual and expected moving propensities beyond what is present through common covariation with the factors that would typically be included in a model of mobility behavior. To assess this point, we regress individuals’ moving outcomes on individuals’ subjective mobility probabilities, and subsequently include the full set of economic and demographic variables that we have been using in our previous regressions. The predictive power of the subjective moving probabilities is shown in Column (1) of Table 2.2. When only the expectation variable is included in the regression, the coeflicient on this variable is highly statistically significant. Since the variable used in the regression ranges from 0 to 1, the coefficient can be interpreted as stating that a 10-percentage point increase in moving expectation increases the probability of a residential relocation by 3.3 percentage points. Figure 2.2 reveals that the relationship between the moving expectations and realiza- tions is nonlinear. Column (2) of Table 2.2 includes a series of dummy variables for the non-zero probability categories to capture the nonlinearity in a nonparametric fashion. The regression coefficients tend to increase in magnitude as the subjective moving probabilities 6The result of the general over-prediction in residential mobility is consistent with the finding of Duncan and Newman (1976). They study the fulfillment rates of job- and housing- related mobility expectations for various demographic, housing, job-related and community characteristics using four waves of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) and find that irrespective of the type of the move, fewer than half of those expecting to move fulfilled these expectations. 43 increase, and are statistically significant for all of the probability categories from 40%. The relationship between the subjective moving probability and the probability that a residen- tial move actually takes place is precisely similar to the pattern found in Figure 2.2. The probability of a move is slightly increasing in the expectation up to 80% category and then jumps rather sharply between 80% and 100% subjective probability categories. In fact, all that the estimates in Column (2) add to Figure 2.2 are the standard errors. The probability variables are jointly significant at the 0.001 level of significance. Including the demographic characteristics in the regressions only has a slight qualitative effect on the relationship between individuals’ subjective moving probabilities and future moves. The expectations variable remains highly significant. To highlight a few of the coef- ficients on the demographic and other variables, those with more than high school education are significantly more likely to make a residential move than their high school graduate coun- terparts. Medical conditions raise the likelihood of moving. Those who own their residences are substantially less likely to move, a finding well documented in the literature. Those with greater housing equity move with lesser probabilities, and current employment diminishes the probability of future moving.7 The estimated coefficients for the observable characteris- tics are almost unchanged in regressions with or without the subjective probability variable. More importantly, the subjective measure remains a strong predictor of future residential mobility, even conditional upon numerous observable characteristics. This means that the predictive power of the subjective probability variable is nearly orthogonal to the predictive ability of the demographic variables. In spite of the apparent overstatement of the expec- tational probabilities, this subjective variable contains very important private information that is otherwise unseen by the econometrician.8 Table 2.3 presents the regression results for the four moving transition waves separately. As suggested visually in Figure 2.2 — Panel B, the estimated coefficients on the dummy 7These results in conjunction with the results in Table 2.1 allow us to explore the extent to which expectations and outcomes of residential mobility qualitatively vary with observables in the same way. For instance, we see that homeowners are less likely to expect to move, just as they are less likely to make a move; those with more than high school education appear more likely to move, and the same group of peOple also reveals larger expectations of moving; and so on. 8All these regressions have been estimated by maximum likelihood probit also. The esti- mated marginal effects from the probit regressions are nearly identical to the reported OLS estimates. 44 variables for the ten non-zero probability categories are very similar for the pooled sample and the individual transition waves. Some of the demographic and other variables, such as, Age, Age-squared, and Home-ownership, are statistically significant both in the pooled and the wave by wave regressions. In fact, almost all the variables that are significant in the pooled regression — for example, White, Less than High School Graduate, More than High School Graduate, At Least Five to Eight Health Conditions, Working for Pay, Number of Children, and Earnings — tend to have the same sign and are significant in at least one of the individual wave regression. The only exception is Net Housing Value, which is statistically significant in the pooled regression, but not significantly estimated in any of the individual wave regressions. 4.3 Item Non-responses in the Subjective Moving Probabilities In the HRS, besides the exact responses that range between 0 and 1 (more specifically, 0 and 100; see Section 2), there are two additional responses that are allowed in the moving expectation question: “don’t know” and “refuse”. We have omitted these observations in the analysis thus far. For the sample population under consideration, the groups that say “don’t know” or “refuse” are extremely small fractions of the population, 1.6% and 0.1%, respectively. The analysis in Table 2.4 depicts that the respondents who either say “don’t know” or give a subjective moving probability of “0.5” are both approximately 5-percentage points more likely to make a residential move than the entire population. In other words, the moving propensities of the two groups with these two probability responses are remarkably close. A “don’t know” response may mean the same as a response of “0.5”, reflecting a belief in a 50-50 chance of future moving. 5 The Heterogeneity in the Accuracy of Prediction Across Population Groups A relevant and important question is whether there are individual characteristics that are associated with people making better predictions about future events. The ability to make more precise forecasts, for instance, might be expected to vary with education and cognitive 45 ability. As a first step in capturing the variations in predictive accuracy, we group people by characteristics and compare the mean subjective probabilities of moving with the mean realized moving prOpensities. The averages of the subjective probabilities and actual moving propensities for various groups are listed in Table 2.5. Mean subjective probabilities exceed actual probabilities for almost every sub—group of population. One notable exception is the group of peOple ages 90—105; it appears that moving is more of a surprise for the oldest adult population than for other demographics. We also find that moving is somewhat of a surprise (under-predicted event) for the Hispanic population, and for peOple without home-ownership. A drawback of this straightforward comparison is that it does not say anything about whether, within a group, those who say they are more likely to move are in fact more likely to do so. It is possible that the group could do very well on average while individual members are doing quite poorly. Therefore, as an alternative we look at the mean squared forecast errors within groups. Let mt denote the binary moving indicator (a 0/1 dummy variable) for whether one moves between periods t-1 and t, and mi] denote the reported subjective probability of moving. Then the sample mean squared forecast errors is simply the average of (mt — mil)“ The mean of squared errors has the advantage that it looks at individual forecast errors and does not allow negative errors to offset positive ones. We report these means for different groups in Column (3) of Table 2.5. In order to interpret these mean squared errors across groups, it is useful to introduce the true (unobserved) probability of moving, pt_ 1, conditional on QM — the information available at the time of the forecast. A difficulty with the mean squared errors is that even if people are predicting as well as they can, if moving is not perfectly predictable given all available information, the mean squared errors will be larger for those whose true probability of moving is closest to 2' To elaborate this point, let us suppose we could form groups that are homogeneous in the conditional probability of moving, pt-1, and everyone reports pm as their subjective probability. By definition, pH is the true expectation of moving outcome, rm, and therefore, the term E(mt — pt_ 1)2 is the variance of mt. Since mt is a binary 0/1 outcome variable, the variance of mt can be written as: pt_1(1 — pt_1). This shows that if in each group everyone reports pm as their subjective probability, then for the group the mean squared error will be pt_1(1 —- pt_1). For different pt_1’s in different groups, the means 46 of squared errors will vary across groups and will be largest for groups with pt_1 closest to %. However. we may not wish to say that groups are better at predicting just because they are less likely to move. One way to address this difficulty in interpreting the mean squared errors across groups is to use a standardized distribution of subjective moving. probabilities (the overall distribu- tion of subjective probabilities) to calculate weighted mean squared errors across groups.9 Weighting the mean-squared errors allows us to account for the differential subjective proba- bility reports by observable characteristics. These weighted mean squared errors are reported in the last column of Table 2.5. Weighting the mean squared errors does seem to reduce the variation across groups compared to the unweighted mean squared errors. This appears to be the case. for instance, for education, marital status, home-ownership, activity limitations, and financial wealth quartiles. The relative subgroup comparisons in weighted means are often very similar to that implied by the basic mean squared errors reported in Column (3), but for certain groups they are quite different. For instance, the usual mean of squared forecast errors is smallest for the least educated of the three education groups that we con- sider, whereas the weighted mean squared errors for this group is the largest among the three groups. Similarly, individuals in the highest quartile of financial wealth have the smallest weighted mean squared errors, though in the usual calculation thosein the second and third quartiles of financial wealth have smaller means of squared errors than people in the highest quartile. Taken as a whole, there does not appear to be a straightforward interpretation of the mean squared errors in assessing group variation in predictive accuracy. 5.1 What do PeOple Report as Subjective Probabilities of Mov- ing? In view of the difficulty in interpreting the mean squared errors, in this section we try to make some sense of what people report as subjective probabilities and also try to say something more about which groups are better at predicting. We assume that individuals are rational based on all available information (9) when they form expectations about the 9In short, we calculate the average squared forecast errors for each group for each reported value of subjective moving probability, and then use the overall distribution of subjective probabilities to calculate the weighted mean squared errors for each group. 47 probability of moving. Then: mtzpt-1+vt ..... (I) where, by definition of pt-1, E(vt|Qt_1) = 0. We hypothesize that when individuals are asked at period t-l about the probability that they will move by period t, what they report is the true probability conditional on the available information, pt, 1, plus some noise that is mean zero for all pt_ 1. Thus, mi; = pi; +6 ..... (2) where, 5 is the noise term that can be positive, negative, or zero, and in the population E(§|Qt_1) = 0. In the data some individuals report a zero probability of moving (i.e., mf.1=0), and nonetheless move, and others report a probability, mi 1, of 1 and do not move. Such behavior can be consistent with the model. The model implies that for such in- dividuals Pt-I is greater than 0 and less than 1, but noise, 6, in their subjective probabilities leads many of them to report the extreme values. If pH varies across peOple, the model suggests that the subjective moving probabilities are informative but noisy. One motivation for this hypothesis is the pattern observed in Figure 2.2 (showing the relationship between moving propensities and subjective moving probabilities), in which the subjective probabilities might be interpreted as reflecting moving probabilities plus something akin to classical measurement error. We assume that the two components of mi] in (2) — pH and 6 —— are uncorrelated (the classical-errors—in-variables (CEV) assumption). We also maintain the assumption that vt is uncorrelated with mg: 1. Horn (1) and (2) we can write: If we estimate this equation by OLS with the inclusion of a constant termlo, it can be shown 10To be specific, we estimate the following by OLS: mt = 50 + 51mg] + ("Ut - 516)- 48 that the plim of B] —— the coeflicient estimate on the subjective mobility measure, mi] —— can be characterized as“: 02 p 2 2 Up + 05 plimBI = ..... (4) where, 03 is the variance of pt_ 1, and of is the variance of the random noise term. 61 would be 1 if we could plug in pH directly instead of the observed mil in the OLS estimation, but plimBI < 1 if mg] is Pt-I plus measurement error. Recall that the estimated coefficients from this OLS regression are what we present in Column (1) of Table 2.2. This regression estimates the curve in Figure 2.2 — Panel A as a straight line. As we can see in Table 2.2, the estimated coefficient BI is 0.334.12 Thus, the pattern in Figure 2.2 and the estimated B] in Table 2.2 appear consistent with our model of what people report as the subjective probabilities of moving. The hypothesis in Equation (2) implies that the observed forecast errors (the deviation between the binary moving outcome and the subjective moving probability) are made up of two components: one component is due to the fact that moving is uncertain —— even given all the available information; and the other component is the random noise element in the subjective probability: mg] 2 pt-) +5 ..... (2) => mt—mf_1 = mt-pH +6. => (mt - 771451)“ = (mt - PM)“ + £2 + 2(mt — Pt-Ilé- If vt and 5 are independent it follows that: => E(mt - 77151)“ = E(mt - Pt-1)2+ 5&2- Since, E(£)=0, E(rnt — mil)? = E(mt — pt_1)2 + Var(§) ..... (5) The left hand side in (5) is the mean squared forecast error. The first term on the right hand side is the variance of mt”, which depends on the true probability of moving, pt_ 1, and for a 11See Wooldridge (2002); p. 75. l2Incidentally, since B1 8: 0.33, it follows from (4) that for the sample population a? z 202. 1 pt_1 is, by definition, the ‘true’ expectation of mt. 49 binary (0, 1) variable mt, is largest when pt_1 is closest to g The second term is a measure of the random noise component in the reported subjective probability. One implication of the model is that the mean of squared forecast errors is larger the closer the average of the true probabilities is to %. Because the hypothesis of what people report as subjective probabilities incorporates a random noise element, if true, the model has the potential to tell us something about which groups predict better. If, for example, it can be shown that the variance of the random noise component is smaller for some groups than others, it could be said that those groups predict better. However, there are some problems with testing and applying this model. One of the problems relates to the possibility of new information arriving between t-1 and t that affects moving. If everyone gets the same shock (that is, all probabilities are affected in the same way) then in a cross section forecast errors will not have zero mean even in large samples. Some years the mean should be positive, some years negative.l4 More critically, following Chamberlain’s (1984) argument, it is possible that new information can affect the moving outcome in ways that could be correlated across individuals with differences in pt_ 1. That is, shocks could affect different people differently, in a way that is correlated with the observable characteristics in a. cross-section. For instance, in some years homeowners may be particularly affected. or low income people.15 This implies that vt in Equation (1) may not be orthogonal to pH across individuals in a particular cross-section. Therefore, in a cross- section or in a short panel like ours, new information can increase forecast errors and can influence the ex-post prediction accuracies of certain groups more than those of the others. The important point to acknowledge is that just because a shock affects a particular group more than the others, and thereby influences the moving outcome of that group in ways not predicted, it should not be concluded that the affected group will consistently make worse predictions than others. To clarify, if, for example, an unexpected downward shock to home values makes it harder for homeowners to move, and they move less than they expected, homeowners may not be consistently poor forecasters. Instead, if our model is correct, we would prefer to say that one group predicts better than another when the former group has l4Econometrically, this issue can be dealt with with time dummies. 15A long enough panel should be able to deal with this econometrically, because the same groups should not get shocks in the same direction repeatedly, but we do not have a long paneL 50 a smaller variance of the noise component than the latter group. There is also a more basic problem with applying this model in assessing group differ- ences in predictive abilities. We observe whether one moves and the subjective probability reported, but we do not observe the true probability. If we did, we could calculate for dif- ferent groups the first term on the right of Equation (5); since we observe for every group the term on the left of Equation (5), we could then infer the second term on the right, and see how it varies across groups. We can, however, consider an approximation of the true probability. We regress the indicator for moving outcome, mt, on a subset of information that the individuals have access to at the time of the forecasts, and take the fitted values from the regression. We calculate the first term on the right of Equation (5) by plugging in these fitted values in place of the pt-1’s. We look into the group variation in the variances of the random noise component in the subjective moving probabilities by considering many different groups segregated by different individual characteristics. We use more than one criterion to disaggregate groups —- the general one in all cases being a classification by gender — in order to retain more homogeneity in true probabilities within groups. Tables 2.6.1 (for women) and 2.6.2 (for men) report the averages of the subjective probabilities, mi 1, and the (approximated) true probabilities, pt, 1, in the first two columns. The mean squared forecast errors for the various groups are reported in Column (3). The next column of Tables 2.6.1 and 2.6.2 reports the noise variances, i.e., the estimates of of, which we derive using Equation (5) with the fitted values replacing the pt_1’s in the calculation. The next two columns report the 31’s and the estimates of 05.16 It appears that the variances of the random noise component differ with individual characteristics. Higher education does not appear to make people better forecasters, whereas better health seems associated with less noisy reports of subjective probabilities.l7 l6The B1 for each group is the estimated coefficient of the subjective probability variable from the regression of moving outcome on subjective moving probability along with a con- stant. The estimates of a? are calculated using Equation (4). Please see Footnote 19 for additional notes. 17Among some other findings, homeowners make better predictions than non-homeowners (Rows 12—13). We find no distinct association between financial assets and the ability to make less noisy forecasts (Rows 14-15). Single people, in general, are more prone to offering noisier predictions than married adults (Rows 16-19). Finally, we do not find evidence that the older adult population are more or less likely to give noisier predictions based on their employment status. 51 It is useful to compare the group differences in noise variances to the group differences in weighted and unweighted mean squared errors that we looked at in Table 2.5. After all, these are two different approaches to trying to answer the same question of whether some groups forecast better than others. For the most part, with respect to any particular individual characteristic(s) we use in grouping people, the subgroup of people that has the largest mean squared errors also happens to give the noisiest forecasts. Of course, larger mean squared errors and larger noise variances are both indicative of relatively worse predictions. For instance, we find that the most educated group has the highest mean of squared errors as well as the largest noise variance among the various education groups. However, the weighted mean squared errors is largest for the least educated group in the sample and smallest for those with high school graduation. Married and partnered people have better forecasts both by the measure of mean squared errors (weighted and unweighted) and that of the noise variances relative to never married and other single people; so does the group of homeowners compared to those without ownership. Those in worse health status — in terms of either activity limitations or subjective health status — have the largest weighted and unweighted mean squared errors and also the largest noise variance relative to those in better physical health. However, we also observe some deviations to this more common pattern of association between the mean squared errors and the noise variances across different subgroups of people. For instance, among the various age groups, the oldest age group of people has the largest mean squared errors. Although the oldest group of women also happens to have the largest noise variance, it is the youngest group of men that makes the noisiest predictions. Also, individuals in the lowest financial wealth quartile have the largest mean squared errors; whereas, women in the highest financial wealth quartile have the largest noise variance. These results regarding the variance of the noise term should be interpreted with caution. The problem is that, as we have mentioned earlier, the expectations may contain additional information not available in observable variables. In fact, if the fitted values were good approximations of the pt_1’s, adding the explanatory variables to an equation for predicting moving should substantially reduce toward zero the coefficient on the subjective probability. We find in Table 2.2 that it only falls a little. The fact that the decline in the estimated coefficient is so small suggests that most of the information in the subjective probabilities 52 is not adequately captured by the set of variables that we are using as regressors. As such, we think that the fitted values from moving regressions do not do a very good job of approximating the pt_1’s.18 Therefore, we should be cautious about putting too much stock in the implied values of the variance of the noise term, and consequently about what we can say about which groups are better at predicting.19 ’ Besides considering the model’s applicability in telling us something about which groups predict better, the other important matter we are concerned about is validating the model itself. In order to investigate whether the model is consistent with the data, we consider a testable implication of the model. The procedure involves estimating Equations (1) and (2), replacing pt_ 1 with a set of explanatory variables — a subset of the information available to the individuals at the time of the forecast. If we maintain the hypothesis that when asked for a subjective probability of moving, peOple respond with the true probability conditional on available information, plus noise of mean zero, then the coefficients on the various ex- planatory variables in the regressions of Equations (1) and (2) should be the same whether the dependent variable is mt or mi 1' Table 2.7 presents the estimated coefficients in the two regressions along with the test statistics for the equality of coefficient for the pooled sample. Failure to reject the hypothesis of equal coefficients for the explanatory variables would be consistent with the hypothesis that reported subjective probabilities are true conditional probabilities plus noise. 1‘v‘We also see in Table 2.1 that the regressor variables have fairly small explanatory power in explaining the variation in the subjective moving probabilities, as captured in the R2 statistics. 19Another issue regarding the estimates of the variance of the noise component makes us concerned about the reliability of the magnitudes of these estimates. We calculate the noise variances reported in Tables 2.6.1 and 2.6.2 using Equation (5), which does not require us to have estimates of 05. However, we can obtain the estimates of 03 directly from the fitted values that approximate the pt,1’s. If we plug in these estimated a]? in Equation (4) along with the 61’s, we obtain another set of estimates for the variances of the noise term. These estimates of 02 are smaller compared to the estimates that we derive using Equation (5) and report in Tables 2.6.1 and 2.6.2. We get the approximations for pt-1’s using a subset of the information available to individuals. As such, for a group, the variance of the true probabilities is likely to be larger than that of the fitted values. If that is the case, then the estimates of 03 we obtain from the fitted values of pH would give lower bound estimates of the variances of the true probabilities. If we plug in these alternative estimates of 03 in Equation (4), we are likely to get lower bound estimates also for of, the variance of the noise element in the subjective moving probability. 53 As apparent in Table 2.7, we reject the hypothesis that the coefficients are jointly equal in the two regressions.2O Thus, if we focus on the joint tests of equality of all coefficients, it seems that the main hypothesis about what people report is wrong. However, it is possible that the main hypothesis is not inaccurate, because the test we are conducting is not entirely a clean test. Note that for the test to be valid, we need to assume that vt in Equation (1) is uncorrelated with pt- 1. But as we have discussed earlier, this assumption may be violated in a cross section even in large samples, because of new information that would affect mt in ways that could be correlated with pH (Chamberlain, 1984). In the absence of this assumption of orthogonality in Equation (1), the rejection of the hypothesis of equal coefficients in the test described above may be due to the deficiency in the test, rather than the inadequacy of the model that we have hypothesized. When we conduct the test of equality of coefficients for one explanatory variable at a time, we fail to reject equality of coefficients across the two regressions for majority of the variables. The variables for which we reject the equality of coeflicients are Age, White, More than High School Graduate, Homeowner, Number of Children, Earnings, Total Household Income, and Working for Pay.21 If our model is correct, it is likely that there exists heterogeneity in the noise in reported moving expectations across population groups. But it is important to acknowledge that a group may predict badly in one year because of unanticipated shocks but this does not imply it will consistently predict badly. Unfortunately, in the absence of being able to account for the Chamberlain critique, and in the absence of a conclusive testable implication to corroborate our hypothesis, we cannot be certain if the group variations that we have shown in Tables 2.6.1 and 2.6.2 accurately capture the extent or direction in which people differ in their noisiness in reported forecasts. 20We also reject the equality of coefficients in every individual transition wave. 21Incidentally, if we reject the equality of coefficients in the two regressions for any variable in any individual transition wave, we often reject the equality of coefficients for that variable in the pooled sample also. Moreover, except for the dummy variable Home-ownership, we do not find the estimated coefficients of the same variables to differ repeatedly in several transition waves. That we reject equality of coeflicients for different observable characteristics in different survey waves (except for home-ownership) gives credence to the hypothesis that if peOple give noisy forecasts, they are random noise, and that individuals are not systematically wrong in reporting their moving expectations. 54 6 Summary and Concluding Remarks The availability of subjective expectations information offers an exciting opportunity to val- idate the importance of expectations in decision-making. However, the results in this paper suggest the need for careful research to assess the empirical relationship between expectations and economic behaviors. The paper provides a comprehensive account of the relationship between the expectation and realization of a binary decision variable for people ages 65 and older in the United States. The results show that the subjective moving expectations are highly significant predictors of subsequent moving. Moving expectations contain additional information beyond that found in demographic variables known to be related to residential mobility. However, the older population appear to over-predict their mobility probabilities during the sample period examined here. At the same time, for approximately 43% of the movers, residential mobility is a completely unforeseen event, and as such, this 43% did not overpredict future moving. Moving appears to be a shock, in particular, for the elderly in their nineties and beyond, and also for a wider age group of older population without home- ownership. There is some evidence that the responses of “don’t know” and “0.5” are similar, that a “don’t know” response instead of representing a lazy response possibly reveals a belief in a 50-50 chance of moving. I In order to understand what people report when they are asked for a subjective probabil- ity of moving, and also to say something about which groups make better moving forecasts, we propose the hypothesis that when asked for the subjective probability of moving, people respond with the true probability conditional on available information plus random noise. This appears to be largely consistent with the pattern of association between the subjective probabilities and the moving propensities. One of our main objectives has been to explore the model’s implications regarding which groups predict future moving better. For instance, if the variance of the random noise component is smaller for some groups than others, then it might be interpreted that those groups make relatively better predictions. However, we have encountered some problems in validating and applying the model. For one thing, because of our reservations about the approximations to the true conditional probabilities that we use in calculating the noise variances, we cannot be confident about the magnitudes of the estimates of these variances for different population groups. In order to validate our model 55 we test whether the coefficients on variables explaining subjective probabilities are the same as when those variables are used to explain moving. The model does not pass, but we argue that the failure might be attributable to the Chamberlain critique. Chamberlain’s argument implies that in the wake of new information, the true conditional probability may no longer reflect the true probability ex-post for certain groups. In a single cross section or in a short panel like the one in this paper, new information can increase forecast errors and can do so differentially for groups with different characteristics. Since we have relied on the mean squared forecast errors and the true conditional probabilities to calculate the measure of noisiness in the subjective probabilities for various groups, we ought to be cautious about the implied values of the variance of the noise term across different groups. 56 Probability Distribution P robability Distribution .9 Figure 2.1: Probability Distribution of Moving Expectations Panel A: All Observations 1 J I I I I I I I .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 Subjective Probability of Moving Probability Distribution of Moving Expectations O— m-i b— #— Panel B: By Mobility Outcome —— — Probability: Movers -- — -- -— -Probability: Non-Movers 1— 2_ . \'\ \ I .1- &k\ -. . //4"'\\.. /\\// I I I I I I I I I .3 4 5 6 7 .8 .9 Subjective Probability of Moving . Probability Distribution of Movmg Expectations 0— L. N 57 Table 2.1: Observable Determinants of Moving Expectations and Relationship between Expectations about Future Moving and Other Events Dependent Variable: Independent Variables Subjective Probability of Moving (1) (2) (3) (4) Age -0.013* -0.017** -0.012* -0.030** (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.008) Age2/100 0.017** 0.010** 0.007+ 0.018** (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) (0.005) Female 0.004 0.006+ 0.005 0.007 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) \thite 0.015** 0.017** 0.012* 0.010 (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) Hispanic -0.021** -0.012 -0.020** -0.013 (0.007) (0.008) (0.007) (0.009) Married -0.034** -0.037** -0.037** -0.035** (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) Widowed -0.031** -0.033** -0.033** -0.025** (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) Less than High School Graduate -0.036** -0.034** -0.035** -0.035** (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) More than High School Graduate 0.040** 0.040** 0.037** 0.039** (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) At Least 1—4 Health Conditions 0.010+ 0.010+ 0.011* 0.013+ (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.007) At Least 5—8 Health Conditions 0.013 0.014 0.018+ 0.015 (0.010) (0.011) (0.010) (0.012) Owns Home / Residence -0.079** -0.080** -0.081** -0.074** (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) Works for Pay Full/Part-Time -0.006 -0.006 -0.005 -0.001 (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) Partly Retired -0.009 -0.009 -0.008 -0.012+ (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) Disabled or Unemployed -0.005 -0.002 —0.007 -0.003 (0.017) (0.019) (0.017) (0.022) Number of Children -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Number of Household Residents -0.006** -0.006** -0.006** -0.008** (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) Earnings “06 0.027 0.033 0.028 -0.125 (0.135) (0.136) (0.135) (0.126) Total Household Income/106 0'1“,” 0°124** “108’” 0°109** (0.038) (0.039) (0.039) (0.041) 58 Table 2.1 Continued Independent Variables: Dependent Variable: Other Subjective Probabilities about Subjective Probability of Moving the Future (1) (a (3) (4) Net Value of Housing “06 0.004 0.005 0.004 0.006 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Net Value of Financial Wealth no" 0-006 0-006 0-006 0005 (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Income Keep Up With Inflation Next 5 Years -0.013* (0.006) Live Next 5 to 15 Yearsf '0°003+ (0.002) Leave Bequests of At Least $10,000 0.008 (0.005) Receive Any Inheritance in Next 10 Years 0.022* (0.009) Constant 0.788** 0.947** 0.745** 1.418** (0.189) (0.205) (0.197) (0.295) Observations 29584 27903 28492 20676 R—squared 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 1. The dependent variable — subjective probability of moving — ranges between 0 and 1, inclusive. 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. + Significant at 10%; * Significant at 5%; ** Significant at 1%. 3. All estimations include dummy variables for survey waves. 4. Weighted regression results reported. 5. For the set of dummy variables Married and Widowed, the excluded category is Divorced, Separated, or Never Married. 6. The omitted education category is High School Graduation. 7. The omitted health condition category is No Doctor-Diagnosed Health Condition. 8. The excluded labor force status variable is Completely Retired (which also includes those identified as Out of Labor Force). 9. fData from the last three transitions waves. Not asked if individuals are 90 or older. 10. Sample sizes in Columns (2) — (4) are conditional on non-missing observations on the additional subjective probabilities that are included in the regression estimations. 59 Fraction M oving F raction Moving Figure 2.2: Moving Expectations and Actual Mobility Panel A: All Transition Waves 45-Degree Line —— Moving Propensity I I I I I I 4 5 6 7 .8 Subjective Probability of .Moving . Expectation and Realization of Residential Mobility o ... b4 0: b— ...— Panel B: By Individual Transition Wave —— Moving Propensity: 1998-2000 — — Moving Propensity: 2000-2002 -- - -- - - Moving Propemity: 2002-2004 - - - — Moving Propensity: 2004-2006 L0- #— .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 Subjective Probability of Moving Expectation and Realization of Residential Mobility o ____. i0 02 60 Table 2.2: Predictiveness of the Subjective Moving Probabilities Dependent Variable: Moving Outcome Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) Subjective Probability of Moving 0.334** 0.317** (0.010) (0.010) Subjective Mobility Probability 10% 0.005 0.004 (0.006) (0.006) Subjective Mobility Probability 20% 0.017 0.013 (0.011) (0.010) Subjective Mobility Probability 30% 0.013 0.006 (0.011) (0.010) Subjective Mobility Probability 40% 0.093** 0082'" (0.023) (0.023) Subjective Mobility Probability 50% 0.089** 0.079** (0.007) (0.007) Subjective Mobility Probability 60% 0.138** 0.123** (0.032) (0.031) Subjective Mobility Probability 70% 0.154** 0.153** (0.035) (0.035) Subjective Mobility Probability 80% 0.208** 0.198** (0.018) (0.018) Subjective Mobility Probability 90% 0.316** 0.310** (0.035) (0.035) Subjective Mobility Probability 100% 0.490** 0.467** (0.017) (0.017) Age -0.032** -0.032** ' (0.007) (0.006) Agez/ 100 0.021** 0.021** (0.004) (0.004) Female -0.004 -0.003 (0.004) (0.004) White 0.029** 0.032** (0.006) (0.006) Hispanic -0.002 -0.002 (0.009) (0.009) Married -0.013 -0.012 (0.009) (0.009) Widowed -0.010 -0.011 (0.009) (0.009) Less than High School Graduate -0.007 -0.010* (0.005) (0.005) More than High School Graduate 0.009+ 0.013** (0.005) (0.005) At Least 1—4 Health Conditions -0.003 -0.002 61 Table 2.2 Continued Dependent Variable: Moving Outcome Independent Variables (1) (2) i3) (4y At Least 5-8 Health Conditions 0.022+ 0.0234- (0.013) (0.013) Owns Home/ Residence -0.097** -0.095** (0.006) (0.006) Works for Pay Full-Time or Part-Time -0.029** -0.032** (0.007) (0.007) Partly Retired -0.010 -0.011+ (0.006) (0.006) Disabled or Unemployed 0.013 0.012 (0.022) (0.022) Number of Children 0.004** 0.004** (0.001) (0.001) Number of Household Residents 0.002 0.000 (0.003) (0.003) Earnings / 1 06 0380* 0348* (0.163) (0.160) Total Household Income/106 ‘0-046 "0'043 (0.030) (0.030) Net Value of Housing/106 '0°011* '0°008+ (0.005) (0.004) Net Value of Financial Wealth/106 0001 0001 (0.003) (0.003) Constant 0.067** 0.080** 1 1.287** 1292'” (0.004) (0.004) (0.246) (0.243) Observations 29584 29584 29584 29584 Ifil-scplared 0.08 0.10 0.10 0.12 1. The dependent variable — Moving Outcome — is a dummy variable equal to 1 if a residential move has occurred between survey waves. 2. Ordinary least squares estimates are reported. Robust standard errors in parentheses. + Significant at 10%; * Significant at 5%; ** Significant at 1%. 3. All estimations include dummy variables for survey waves. 4. Weighted regression results reported. 5. For the set of dummy variables Married and Widowed, the excluded category is Divorced, Separated, or Never Married. 6. The omitted education category is High School Graduation. 7. The omitted health condition category is No Doctor-Diagnosed Health Condition. 8. The excluded labor force status variable is Completely Retired (which also includes those identified as Out of Labor Force). 62 Table 2.3: Predictiveness of the Subjective Moving Probabilities By Individual Transition Wave Dependent Variable: Moving Outcome Independent Variables 1998- 2000- 2002- 2004- 2000 2002 2004 2006 Subjective Mobility Probability 10% 0.031* 0.000 -0.011 0.004 (0.014) (0.014) (0.012) (0.011) Subjective Mobility Probability 20% 0.027 0.011 0.013 0.002 (0.021) (0.022) (0.022) (0.019) Subjective Mobility Probability 30% -0.006 0.011 -0.003 0.017 (0.016) (0.023) (0.021) (0.020) Subjective Mobility Probability 40% 0.090+ 0.043 0.101* 0.092+ (0.050) (0.042) (0.045) (0.048) Subjective Mobility Probability 50% 0.076** 0.089** 0.081** 0.072** (0.013) (0.016) (0.015) (0.014) Subjective Mobility Probability 60% 0.190* 0.166** 0.025 0.088+ (0.075) (0.058) (0.061) (0.050) Subjective Mobility Probability 70% 0.047 0.239** 0201* 0.120* (0.054) (0.078) (0.081) (0.061) Subjective Mobility Probability 80% 0.210** 0.226** 0.154** 0.198** (0.037) (0.039) (0.035) (0.032) Subjective Mobility Probability 90% 0.304** 0.290** 0.294** 0.330** (0.066) (0.073) (0.073) (0.064) Subjective Mobility Probability 100% 0.433** 0.426** 0.455** 0.540** (0.036) (0.035) (0.034) (0.031) Age -0.021+ -0.024+ -0.031* -0.045** (0.013) (0.013) ‘ (0.013) (0.013) Age2/100 0.015+ 0.016+ 0.020* 0.031** (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.008) Female 0.010 -0.009 -0.011 -0.000 (0.008) (0.009) (0.009) (0.008) White 0.029** 0.044** 0.008 0.049** (0.010) (0.013) (0.014) (0.011) Hispanic 0.013 0.014 -0.037* 0.009 (0.018) (0.021) (0.017) (0.017) Married -0.001 0.018 -0.019 -0.042* (0.016) (0.019) (0.018) (0.017) Widowed -0.010 0.019 -0.009 -0.038* (0.016) (0.019) (0.018) (0.018) Less than High School Graduate -0.019* -0.012 -0.009 -0.001 (0.009) (0.011) (0.011) (0.010) More than High School Graduate 0.005 0.018+ 0.009 0.023* (0.009) (0.011) (0.010) (0.009) At Least 1—4 Health Conditions -0.001 -0.010 0.010 -0.007 (0.009) (0.013) (0.012) (0.013) 63 Table 2.3 Continued Dependent Variable: Moving Outcome Independent Variables 1998- 2000- 2002- 2004- 2000 2002 2004 2006 At Least 5—8 Health Conditions -0.017 , -0.001 0.030 0.047* (0.022) (0.030) (0.024) (0.023) Owns Home / Residence -0.085** -0.138** -0.071** -0.089** (0.012) (0.014) (0.013) (0.012) Works for Pay Full-Time or Part-Time -0.003 -0.062** -0.038* -0.024+ (0.014) (0.014) (0.017) (0.012) Partly Retired -0.001 -0.033* -0.017 0.008 (0.012) (0.013) (0.013) (0.012) Disabled or Unemployed 0.019 0.060 -0.033 0.003 (0.033) (0.055) (0.039) (0.047) Number of Children 0.005** 0.003 0.006** 0.002 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Number of Household Residents -0.000 -0.001 -0.003 0.003 (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005) Earnings / 106 0.354 0.146 0.516+ 0.108 (0.323) (0.309) (0.290) (0.210) Total Household Income/106 -0.035 -0.099 0.051 -0.049 (0.086) (0.082) (0.066) (0.039) Net Value of Housing/10" -0.010 -0.025 -0.034 -0.004 (0.006) (0.051) (0.022) (0.004) Net Value of Financial Wealth / 106 -0.022** 0.025 -0.001 0.002 (0.008) (0.018) (0.005) (0.004) Constant 0.820+ 1.064* . 1.322** 1.763** (0.476) (0.503) (0.475) (0.478) Observations 7494 6987 7292 7811 R-squared 0.12 0.11 0.10 0.15 1. The dependent variable — Moving Outcome — is a dummy variable equal to 1 if a residential move has occurred between survey waves. 2. Ordinary least squares estimates are reported. Robust standard errors in parentheses. + Significant at 10%; * Significant at 5%; ** Significant at 1%. S” Weighted regression results reported. 4. For the set of dummy variables Married and Widowed, the excluded category is Divorced, Separated, or Never Married. 5. The omitted education category is High School Graduation. F" The omitted health condition category is No Doctor-Diagnosed Health Condition. 7. The excluded labor force status variable is Completely Retired (which also includes those identified as Out of Labor Force). 64 Table 2.4: Moving Propensity by Reported Subjective Moving Probability Subjective Moving Probability Moving Propensity Exact Non-Focal and Focal Responses (n=29584) 12.12 Probability Response 2 0 (n=19308) 8.13 Probability Response = 0.5 (n=3181) 17.08 Probability Response = 1 (n=1037) 57.16 Probability Response 2 Don’t Know (490) 16.86 Probability Response 2 Refusal (n=23) 20.31 Note: Weighted tabulations are reported. 65 Table 2.5: Subjective Moving Probabilities, Moving Propensities, and Mean Squared Forecast Errors amoniDifferent Groups of Population Subjective Mean Weighted Moving Moving Squared Mean Groups of Population Probabilities Propensity Errors Squared Errors? Full Sample of Population 15.60 12.12 0.1321 -- Gender Men 15.27 11.77 0.1276 0.1301 Women 15.83 12.36 0.1352 0.1334 Education Less than HS Graduate 11.41 11.03 0.1201 0.1353 High School Graduate 15.06 1 1.77 0.1294 0.1304 More than HS Graduate 19.01 13.21 0.1429 0.1343 Age 65 — 69 17.42 12.55 0.1371 0.1306 70 — 74 14.92 10.62 0.1200 0.1231 75 — 79 14.48 11.34 0.1233 0.1273 80 - 89 15.13 14.08 0.1480 0.1481 90 — 105 12.87 17.70 0.1827 0.1902 Race 8: Ethnicity White 15.79 12.31 0.1324 0.1320 Black and Other 13.82 10.31 0.1295 0.1334 Hispanic 11.70 11.98 0.1411 0.1555 Non~Hispanic 15.79 12.13 0.1317 0.1311 Marital Status Married or Partnered 14.96 10.82 0.1195 0.1228 Divorced / Widowed 16.38 14.02 0.1504 0.1467 Never Married 21.76 13.57 0.1551 0.1345 Ownership Homeowners 14.18 9.55 0.1142 0.1200 Non-Homeowners 21.02 21.93 0.2006 0.1871 Employment Working for Pay 16.81 10.30 0.1258 0.1198 Partly Retired 15.79 1 1.23 0.1226 0.1227 Completely Retired 15.43 12.39 0.1337 0.1342 66 Table 2.5 Continued Subjective Mean Weighted Groups of Population Moving Moving Squared Mean Probabilities Propensity Errors Squared Errorst Limitations in Activities No ADL 15.58 11.75 0.1276 0.1279 At Least One ADL 15.75 14.37 0.1596 0.1578 Self-Rated Health Status Excellent or Very Good 15.95 11.73 0.1276 0.1270 Good 15.61 11.73 0.1277 0.1279 Fair or Poor 15.04 13.21 0.1447 0.1458 Net Non-Housing Financial Wealth Lowest Quartile 14.05 13.29 0.1425 0.1455 Second Quartile 14.85 12.11 0.1286 0.1313 Third Quartile 15.53 11.53 0.1280 0.1285 Highest Quartile 17.74 11.69 0.1305 0.1253 1. 1' In the last column, the means of squared forecast errors are weighted by the overall population distribution of the subjective probability reports. See page 12 for details. 2. Weighted tabulations are reported. 67 68 2.23 N82 38d 8m; 8.: mm: agus 23:0 53? 3.055”: “semi a... 32? as $56 3.3 mag $3.0 m2; m3; scans 2830 .23.? Boss: 3033 a. 32? $3 $23 $02 83.0 38.0 3.8 03.0. @2ch mEmuocBOoEoI 3055 anion mow< 33 $86 $2 $86 3: S 03 .3: axcus “2.3383880: 65 filo: 89.. as 385 Kg ago 826 2.: on: Ammsmus on? .5. Soars 81: am... cc 8:; $de 236 $03 3.: 3.: gins .5... 25 as: a... 55 gums 8? 8c 8:; 3:5 88.0 326 at: No: 3&ch 53: “SEE”: a Elmo 3? € :56 8mg :86 $30 8.: 40.: scans 53: Bow E>>S=§m & Elmo 8? as $5.0 ammo 886 ES oh: 8.: ammfie c8335 3 as, 8 c8550 3 $5 :3 65 Sumo 8?. swam 6 823 83.0 886 S: S 2.: 8.: gang couaswso m: as, 8 c8325 mm 55 a“: as, gums 8w< coca“: GS N23 as? :25 2:5 8. : 5: swans 89.525 m: 55 an: as, Elmo 3? 3V $56 Emoo 68¢ 32.0 8. : 2.2 :33...ch couasuso m: 56 so: 55 films a? A: 0:3 8de 886 82¢ a: mo: smsmus 3:.on 8?. 6 $23 ammo 82; $25 5.: 3: fixing Enos 8?. 3 85¢ omomd $86 22.0 3.: R: afimns aims 8? 6 F a a A gov A wbv 3.3305 £33on .N N 38.5 marrow): 9652 cows—:mom .«o muscumvnnsm : cm :0 d we a A wuss m @8580 883% ZMEOB ougtfiw BfiEumm 855$ :82 532 982 mcoflsuoo mm 32 5 muohm amwouucm flown—arm E32 “Eula—Imam #6."... Bash. 01.5 80w Emanumem war/OE 2.: mo omfiog or: 8.“ 2:00 05 8 95% a 5m bafiunoum wGFOE EcoEficoU :82 2.: 6085.588 Now .3303? paw “0880060 .woflozv £288: 85: movflucm 33% .N .95th3 316.800“ H. .8 080.0 88.0 008.0 88.0 8.8 8.8 A0888 00585-82 :5 8:00 880 88.0 88.0 8.0: 8.: 08:an 2982: A08 8800 880 8.8.0 880 8.8 8.8 A8820 0888 322088 8'8 83 285 A80 8 8.0 88.0 080.0 008.0 8.: 8.8 60820 0203: 322088 00.00 an? 000:: A80 880 800.0 880 N0: :0 :.: 8.: A805 8283 0018 a? 28% A5 880 8:0 080.0 88.0 a: 8.8 $0an0 8.28? 0018 8? BENZ A80 A200 0 F A E A wbv 353on £5390 .N. N 808m war/OE was/OE Cayuga—om mo mascuUA—Sm A “Q mo Ha O . . . M0 083$ 0.8.0.680 2,8053 2300? 85:5/ voyafiumm uudmta> :32 :82 C32 02.8.80 8.08 20.8. 69 852300 m— va0.0 000m .0 $.N00 0MNA.0 0A; A 55.0 thmd 300.0 32.0 0N.mA 00N00 ovum .0 300.0 00000 00. AN 005.0 ommm .0 MNN00 0000.0 no.0 0NA0.0 vwmmd VAN0.0 3:0 5.: mm A00 Aw AN.0 3840.0 Aom A.0 N A .3 0m A00 hmwmd 0000.0 003.0 vaA m0 A00 mmom .0 030.0 own A .0 vaA 3&00 h Awmd $00.0 mmw A .0 000A om A00 00000 0Nm0.0 hvad No.0A mm 5.0 wmvmd vomod m A A A0 5.3 3. A00 Amen .0 m0m0.0 ANv A .0 mm.mA VM 5.0 m 0mm .0 N500 0mm A.0 was“: 0m 50 Nomm .0 080.0 AoA A0 3.3 3. A00 hommd wmm00 0NvA.0 00.2 -HMM a _A AA AN 3 A03 ALQ A N 308m w:A>02 .00 u w .0 00.81% 8:020:00 8:0:«> wouwegm 00:88; 502 :32 00.3 mm.vA 0A.NN \:A.NA 00.2 A04; AwéA mw.0A No.00. 000 A 00A A 3.3 00.: mw.mA $0.: A8880 2330 .038 383: 08:08 a 32? A80 A8810 08330 £88 383: :33 a. 23? A80 A8030 02333850: 3063 8:08 803 A80 8.8ch 02333850: 53 8:00 89: A80 A8830 .00.: 32. 3053 8:8 83 A5 :8ch 09. 30 85 E .03 8:8 80.: A0: 8:8 .23: 8&8: a 8:8 836 A8830 .23: 080 380383: a 8:8 88.. A00 AmhMHGv GOflmSUdumv m: a; :0 GOUwAa—kumv m: 5% a“; .03 8:8 new... 2008 6 AowaAH—c cowasvfio mi 02.8 :0 :ougvfimu m: 55 9.3 53 8:8 80.: 0332 A00 8880 803080 8: 55 as: .03 8:8 83 00 A8830 803080 W: 5.0 so: 33 8:8 83. 00 A8830 88.8 as? A0 8830 8:00 88: A8 @8010 8:8 33 A: £338: 0838: w:A>02 2500782 :82 :oflaAnnAom .3 8390050 Z2 02 :A 80th umwoouom 003m 532 05 maxim ”N.0.N 030,—. 70 “as: :00 38:93.5 wE>o2 “.5 00 omfiu: 05 mm 0E8 05 mm 050% a :00 8052—05 m5>02 8:020:00 :82 05 60.503538 km 003033 05 003803 008020 02:88 .55: $0305 flwfim .v .msouwbsw 31691.0 0.8 «Sod 88¢ 88.0 886 8.: 8.8 88 W3 9585-82 :3 85.0 885 88.0 8...; 8.: 8. : 9880 25%: 88 8.8.0 88.0 283 E 8.0 8.3 8.8 Amwmnav can”: 883800 8:8 83 2ch a: 8:3 8:3 85.0 8.26 8.2 8.: 88ch 8:8: 322300 8:8 83 BE“: 8: 88.0 v83 8: 3 88.5 8.8 8.8 82ch 8288 8:8 8w... 288 8: 88.0 885 888 828 8.9 8.8 afine 828? 8:8 we? BENZ G: 30 A A :00 A 000 5538: 3338: Am A m 2080 wE>02 mE>02 cofiflsmom .Ao mascumvézm & 0 0 n w 00 vuuuswm 8:020:00 oZuuoEDm 7A2 3:825 voyafiuwm 35:8, :32 :32 :82 355.80 N3 28... 71 Table 2.7: Testing for Equality of Coefficients on Variables Explaining Subjective Probabilities of Moving and Moving Outcome SUbiCCthC p-valuc for Probability Chi-Squared 0f Movmg Test Statistic Moving Outcome for Equality of Coefficients Testing for Egality of Coefficients on All Explanatory Variables -- -- 0.0000 Testing for Equality of Coefficients for Each Explanatory Variable Age -0.036** -0.013** 0.0004 (0.006) (0.005) Age2/100 0.021** 0.017* 0.3047 (0.004) (0.003) Female -0.002 0.004 0.1549 (0.004) (0.003) White 0.034** 0.015** 0.0096 (0.007) (0.006) Hispanic -0.008 -0.021** 0.2135 (0.009) (0.008) Married -0.023** -0.034** 0.2057 (0.007) (0.006) Widowed -0.020* -0.031** 0.1717 (0.007) (0.006) Less than High School Graduate -0.021** -0.036** 0.3358 (0.005) (0.004) More than High School Graduate 0.021** 0.040** 0.0002 (0.004) (0.004) Homeowner -0.122** -0.079** 0.0000 (0.005) (0.004) At Least 1—4 Health Conditions -0.001 0.010* 0.1268 (0.006) (0.005) At Least 5—8 Health Conditions 0026* 0.013 0.2882 (0.011) (0.009) Number of Children 0.004** -0.001 0.0000 (0.001) (0.001) Number of Household Residents -0.002 -0.006** 0.1802 (0.002) (0.002) Earnings/106 0.389** 0.027 0.0116 (0.128) (0.107) Total Household Income/106 '0'009 0116” 0'00” (0.036) (0.030) Net Value of Housing/106 ‘0-009 0004 02638 (0.007) (0.006) 72 Table 2.7 Continued Moving Subjective p-value for Outcome Probability Chi-Squared of Moving Test Statistic for Equality of Coefficients Net Value of Financial Wealth/106 0002 0006* 0'25 11 (0.003) (0.002) Work for Pay -0.031** -0.006 0.0017 (0.007) (0.006) Partly Retired -0.012* -0.009 0.5855 (0.006) (0.005) Disabled or Unemployed 0.011 -0.005 0.4599 (0.019) (0.016) The estimated coefficients from OLS regressions on the pooled sample are reported in the first two columns for the two dependent variables — Moving Outcome and Subjective Probability of Moving. Standard errors are in parentheses. 73 Appendix Table A.2.1: Sample Selection Criteria Number of Observations Total Number of Core Interview Obtained1 97729 If Cohort and Age Eligiblez’ 3 84421 86-380/0 If At Least Two Successive Interviews Obtained4 61688 63°120/ 0 If At Least Age 65 in the First of Two Successive 35720 36.55% Interviews If Subjective Probability of Moving Non-Missing 31541 32.27% If Moving Outcome in the Subsequent Interview 31541 32.27% Non-missing If Non-missing Respondent and Household Characteristics If Race/ Ethnicity Non-missing 31522 32.26% If Home-Ownership Non-missing 31339 32.07% If Number of Resident Children Non-missirg 29584 30.27% 21384, 19580, 18167, 20129, and 18469 observations, respectively, from the 1998, 2000, 2002, 2004, and 2006 HRS Surveys. Observations belong to the four cohorts in the Health and Retirement Study: AHEAD (1890-1923), CODA (1924-1930), HRS (1931-1941), and War Babies (1942-1947). Note that in 2004 another cohort — the Early Baby Boomer (EBB) cohort (1948-1953) — was introduced in the 5M4}, respondents from which are not part of our analyses. 20002, 18139, 16685, 15237, and 14358 observations, respectively, from the 1998, 2000, 2002, 2004, and 2006 HRS Surveys. 26260 of these observations — 42.57% - are male. 74 Table A.2.2: Summa Statistics of Variables Variables MearflStandard Deviation) Moving Propensity 12.12 Subjective Probability 15.60 (0.27) Age 73.87 (6.42) Female 0.59 White 0.90 Hispanic 0.05 Married or Partnered 0.60 Widowed 0.31 Separated or Divorced or Never Married 0.09 Less than High School Graduation 0.26 High School Graduation 0.36 More than High School Graduation 0.38 Home-Ownership 0.79 1-4 Medically Diagnosed Conditions 0.84 5-8 Medically Diagnosed Conditions 0.04 No ADL 0.86 At Least One ADL 0.14 Number of Children 3.36 (2.11) Household Size 1.95 (0.92) Labor Market Earnings (in 2000 dollars) 3,405.63 (16911.7) Total Household Income (in 2000 dollars) 42,450.70 (61943.3) Net Value of Housing (in 2000 dollars) Net Value of Financial Wealth (in 2000 dollars) 115,851 (279968) 140,256 (661678) Works for Pay Full-Time or Part-Time 0.09 Partly Retired 0.11 Disabled or Unemployed 0.01 Completely Retired 0.79 Number of Observations 29584 Note: Weighted means are reported. 75 References [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [61 [7] [81 [9] [10] [111 [12] [13] Bassett, W. F. and R. L. Lumsdaine. 2001. “Probability Limits: Are Subjective Assess- ments Adequately Accurate?”. The Journal of Human Resources; Vol. 36, No. 2: pp. 327-363. Bernheim, B. D. 1988. “Social Security Benefits: “An Empirical Study of Expectations and Realizations”. In Ricardo-Campbell, R. and E. P. Lazear edited Issues in Contem- porary Retirement; Hoover Institution Press; Stanford University, Stanford, California. Bernheim, B. D. 1989. “The Timing of Retirement: A Comparison of Expectations and Realizations”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Economics of Aging; Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. Bernheim, B. D. 1990. “How Do Elderly Form Expectations: An Analysis of Responses to New Information”. In Wise, D. A. edited Issues in the Economics of Aging; Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. Bérch-Supan, A., D. McFadden, and R. Schnabel. 1996. “Living Arrangements: Health and Wealth Effects”. In Wise, D. A. edited Advances in the Economics of Aging; Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. Bérch-Supan, A. 1990. “A Dynamic Analysis of Household Dissolution and Living Ar- rangement Transitions by Elderly Americans”. In Wise, D. A. edited Issues in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. B6rch-Supan, A. 1989. “Household Dissolution and the Choice of Alternative Living Arrangements among Elderly Americans”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Chamberlain, G. 1984. “Panel Data”. In Griliches, Z. and M. D. Intriligator edited Handbook of Econometrics; Volume 2. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Clark, R. L. and D. A. Wolf. 1992. “Proximity of Children and Elderly Migration”. In Rogers, A. edited Elderly Migration and Population Distribution; Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. Das, M. and A. van Soest. 1999. “A Panel Data Model for Subjective Information on Household Income Growth”. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization; Volume 40, Issue 4: pp. 409-426. Das, M. and A. van Soest. 2001. “Expected versus Realized Income Changes: A Test of Rational Expectations Hypothesis”. Center for Economic Research Discussion Paper 105. Tilburg University, Tilburg, The Netherlands. Duncan, G. J. and S. J. Newman. 1976. “Expected and Actual Mobility”. Journal of American Institute of Planners; Vol. 42(2): pp. 174-186. Dominitz, J. and C. Manski. 1997. “Using Expectations Data to Study Subjective In- come Expectations”. Journal of American Statistical Association; Vol. 92, No. 439: pp. 855—862. 76 [14] Engelhardt, G. V. and J. Gruber. 2006. “Social Security and the Evolution of Elderly Poverty”. in Auerbach, A., D. Card, and J. Quigley edited Public Policy and the Dis- tribution of Income; Russell Sage Press; pp. 259-287. [15] Feinstein, J. S. 1996. “Elderly Health, Housing and Mobility”. In Wise, D. A. edited Advances in the Economics of Aging; Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. . [16] Haider, S. J. and M. Stephens Jr. 2007. “Is there a Retirement-Consumption Puzzle? Evidence Using Subjective Retirement Expectations”. The Review of Economics and Statistics; Vol. 89(2): pp. 247-264. [17] Hurd, M., D. McFadden, and L. Can. 1998. “Subjective Survival Curves and Life Cycle Saving Behavior”. In Wise, D. A. edited Inquiries in the Economics of Aging. The University of Chicago Press. [18] Hurd, M. and K. McGarry. 2002. “The Predictive Validity of Subjective Probabilities of Survival”. The Economic Journal; Vol. 112 (October): pp. 966-985. [19] Hurd, M. and K. McGarry. 1995. “The Evaluation of Subjective Probabilities of Survival in the Health and Retirement Study”. The Journal of Human Resources; Vol. 30: pp. s268-292. [20] Lillard, L. A. and R. J. Willis. 2001. “Cognition and Wealth: The Importance of Prob- abilistics Thinking”. Michigan Retirement Research Center Research Paper No. WP 2001—007. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1084559. [21] Loughran, D., C. Panis, M. Hurd and M. Reti. 2001. “Analysis of Retirement Planning”. Project Memoranda PM—1244-SSA, Santa Monica: RAND, California. [22] J appelli, T. and L. Pistaferri. 2000. “Using Subjective Income Expectations to Test for Excess Sensitivity of Consumption to Predicted Income Growth”. European Economic Review; Vol. 44: pp. 337-358. [23] Manski, C. F. and J. D. Straub. 2000. “Worker Perceptions of Job Insecurity in the Mid-1990s: Evidence from the Survey of Economic Expectations”. Journal of Human Resources; Vol. 35, No. 3: pp. 447-479. [24] Maestas, N. 2007. “Back to Work: Expectations and Realizations of Work after Retire- ment”. RAND Labor and Population Working Paper Series: WR—196-2. Santa Monica: RAND, California. [25] Rohwedder, S and K. J. Kleinjans. 2006. “Dynamics of Individual Information about Social Security”. RAND Corporation manuscript. [26] Souleles, N. S. 2002. “Expectations, Heterogeneous Forecast Errors, and Consumption: Micro Evidence from the Michigan Consumer Sentiment Surveys”. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking; Vol. 36, No. 1: pp 39—72. [27] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 2004. “Aging and Housing Equity: Another Look”. In Wise, D. A. edited Perspectives on the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. 77 [28] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 1990. “But They Dont Want to Reduce Housing Equity”. In Wise, D. A. edited Issues in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. [29] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 1989. “Aging, Moving and Housing Wealth”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. [30] Wooldridge, J. M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. The MIT Press; Cambridge, Massachusetts. 78 Chapter 3 Do THE ELDERLY SPEND DOWN THEIR HOUSING WEALTH? 1 Introduction Many papers have examined the role housing wealth plays in the life-cycle consumption and saving decisions of individuals. The cornerstone of the life-cycle theory that guides most of the economic research on the adequacy of retirement savings is the idea of consumption smoothing. In its basic formulation, the life-cycle model posits that saving behavior is forward-looking and is driven by the desire to maintain consumption during low-income periods. Thus, an important implication of the life-cycle model is that individuals will spend down their savings during retirement (Modigliani and Brumberg, 1954; Modigliani, 1986). Refinement of the standard model, allowing for uncertainty, precautionary saving and accidental bequests, may affect the age after which one should start observing wealth decumulation. It does not, however, change the basic implication that individual wealth should eventually tend to fall with age. The relative size of housing equity in the asset portfolios of older American households suggests its potential importance for post-retirement consumption. According to the 2001 Survey of Consumer Financesl, over 80 percent of all households with heads aged 65 and older owned a home, and these homes were valued at nearly $3.17 trillion. Including the $781 billion of other residential real estate (largely second homes), the total value of residential lSource: Apgar and Di (2006). Evidence on the assets of the elderly is also reported in Diamond and Hausman (1984); Hurd and Wise (1989); Kennickell and Shack-Marquez (1992); Poterba and Samwick (2001); and Sinai and Souleles (2007). 79 real estate owned by the older households increased to $3.95 trillion. Consequently, in 2001 residential real estate accounted for some 30 percent of the nearly $13.2 trillion in aggregate asset holding of seniors.2 Given such significance of housing wealth in the asset portfolio of the elderly, this paper examines the long contested issue of whether the elderly draw down their housing wealth during retirement. 7 The evidence in the literature on downsizing of housing wealth in later life is fairly mixed. Sheiner and Weil (1992), Skinner (1996), and Heiss, Hurd, and B6rch-Supan (2005) suggest that individuals at sufficiently older ages tend to tap into housing wealth. Sheiner and Weil (1992), using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), estimate that among households entering very old ages owning a home, just 41% still own when the surviving spouse dies. Skinner (1996) also uses the PSID data and shows that if the elderly downsize, 69 cents of each dollar of housing equity is spent. This evidence is taken to interpret that the elderly consume housing wealth. More recently, Heiss et a1. (2005) have used data on the AHEAD cohort from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) to explore if the elderly downsize housing by focusing on homeownership rates. They find that ownership is reduced with age. Other studies (Merrill; 1984, Feinstein and McFadden; 1989, and Venti and Wise; 1989, 1990, 2004), contrary to the ones noted above, suggest that homeowners typically do not use their housing wealth to support non-housing consumption in later life. Feinstein and McFadden (1989) look into the probability of residential mobility among the elderly relying on data from the PSID. Several of the other papers focus on changes in home equity exploiting different data sources; for instance, Merrill (1984) and Venti and Wise (1989; 1990) use data from the Retirement History Survey (RHS), and Venti and Wise (2004) use the first four waves of the HRS as well as data from eight panels of the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP). All of these papers reach the general conclusion that, unless there is a change in family composition, there is little evidence that families reduce their housing wealth with age. 2In contrast, only 21.1 percent of all households with heads aged 65 and older owned publicly traded stocks. Expanding the concept of stock ownership to combine the direct ownership of publicly traded stocks plus stocks owned indirectly through mutual funds, retirement accounts and other managed assets, the share of seniors owning stocks increased to just 36.8 percent. Under this expanded definition, seniors owned nearly $3.4 trillion in stocks, an amount that represented 25.8 percent of their aggregate asset holdings (Source: Aizcorbe, Kennickell, and Moore; 2003. Tabulations done by the Joint Center for Political and Economic Studies based on 2001 Survey of Consumer Finances). 80 In this paper, we investigate changes in housing wealth with data from the 1998 and 2004 surveys of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS). The HRS is a national longitudinal biennial survey offering a rich source of information on the lives of older Americans, their health and economic status. We use data on individuals from the 1998 survey and follow them into the 2004 survey. Venti and Wise (2004) also use data from the HRS (1992—1998) for the HRS and AHEAD cohorts. The pOpulation representation in the 1998 HRS survey allows us to take advantage of a larger sample encompassing a broader age range. In its simplest version, the life-cycle theory posits the systematic accumulation of assets during the working life and gradual decumulation during retirement. Therefore, our focus is on the already-retired individuals to determine if retirees spend down their home equity. Previous studies have examined individuals of a particular age range irrespective of their labor force status. Our sample design is more consistent with exploring possible wealth draw down in later life. In examining whether housing wealth declines during retirement, we emphasize exploring heterogeneity across population groups in housing wealth adjustments. In the past, short of selling their homes there was virtually no other alternative for the elderly to extract housing wealth. In recent years, markets for home equity lines of credit and reverse mortgages have deveIOped for tapping into home equity. Although these markets still remain small, they are gradually expanding. Thus, these financial instruments potentially offer increasing opportunities for the elderly to extract home equity. In view of this, we briefly examine, to the extent allowed by the HRS data, the evidence on housing equity adjustments through a type of such instruments. Our analysis demonstrates that for non-mover retirees there is no systematic decline in housing equity. But for retiree—movers there is a decline in the median housing equity starting at age 71, and a decline in the mean housing equity from age 76. The mean change in housing equity is $9,866.2 (-$1,769.5, adjusting for two outliers) and the median change is —$8,112.3 for all retiree-movers. The decline in housing equity stems from homeowners who give up ownership altogether. Typically, housing equity increases for retiree-movers who buy new houses. We find evidence of significant heterogeneity in housing equity adjustments at retirement. Nearly a quarter of the retiree-movers report that they are moving to downsize, and they do. Those with low non—housing wealth and with low income reduce housing equity 81 significantly more than their respective counterparts. Retiree-movers experiencing widowing or divorce reduce housing equity substantially more than those without similar experience. It is important to put the findings in this study in the context of the results reported in the literature. Our results are similar to the findings in some of the papers in both strands of the literature that conclude in support of and against evidence for housing wealth draw down in later life. To a large extent, the different conclusions in the two sets of papers are the product of differences in interpretation. Using data from the Health and Retirement Study, Venti and Wise (2004), for instance, find evidence of a decline in movers’ housing equity in both one-person and two-person house- holds. Their reported median decline in housing equity is very similar in magnitude to that of ours. As in their analysis, we also find that the median housing equity declines beginning at age 75. Venti and Wise (2004) also note that the large reductions in equity are typically observed only for homeowners who move and discontinue homeownership. Nonetheless, they conclude that housing wealth is not spent down because most of the older households continue to own housing, and overall housing equity appears to increase in every two-year interval.3 Feinstein and McFadden’s (1989) conclusion that the elderly households do not reduce housing equity is largely grounded on the finding that wealthier households are less likely to move and to downsize. This also is consistent with our findings. On the other side of the literature, when Skinner (1996) concludes that there is evidence of downsizing he is basing that conclusion on a mere 8.3% of his sample that moved and reduced their housing equity. Sheiner and Weil (1992) and Heiss, Hurd and B6rch-Supan (2005) find evidence of average levels of home-ownership declining significantly with age. Heiss et 81. note that for older two-person households home—ownership begins to fall from age 71, which is in line with the finding in our study. To a large extent indeed, our results are consistent with the existing evidence in both sides of the literature, and the different emphases of these papers mostly 3Venti and Wise (2004) additionally look into overall changes in housing equity in the SIPP data and find no evidence of downsizing, which is consistent with what we find. Venti and Wise (1989) report a decline in median housing equity for movers during the 1973—1975 interval by $6,044.3 (in 2004 dollars). But they also find that housing equity increased for movers during three of the five intervals they look into, and that in four of the five intervals more than half of the movers increased housing equity post-move. Thus, they conclude that those who move, on average, do not withdraw wealth from housing equity. Merrill (1984) retains initial non-homeowners in the sample of movers and she has a relatively younger sample, both of which may explain why she fails to find any indication of a decline in housing equity for movers. 82 are reflective of differences in interpretation of what is in the data. The outline of the chapter is as follows. The next section describes the data used in this study. Section 3 narrates the extent to which the retirees reduce their housing equity as they age. Section 4 examines whether the elderly spend down non-housing wealth as they age, and how this compares to individuals’ extraction of housing equity. Subsequently in this section, we investigate whether certain individuals for whom we might expect to see housing draw down tap into home equity more. Section 5 concludes. 2 The Data We use data on individuals from the four cohorts in the Health and Retirement Study (HRS): AHEAD (born between 1890—1923), CODA (born between 1924-1930), HRS (born between 1931—1941), and War Babies (born between 1942-1947). The population of inference is adults born prior to 1948. We explore the change in housing wealth of individuals, and not that of the household as a unit. Since our objective is to investigate housing wealth draw down during retirement, we restrict our sample to homeowners in 1998. Table A31 in the Appendix describes the sample construction steps. We follow the cohort and age- eligible respondents from the 1998 survey to the 2004 survey, and retain a sample of 11,957 observations on retirees and non-retirees. The HRS over-sampled blacks, Hispanics, and Floridians. For this, we use respondent-level sampling weights in our analysis. Table A.3.2 describes some key features about the sample in 1998 and 2004 and presents the descriptive statistics for the variables used in this paper. As expected, individuals are less likely to be married or partnered (primarily due to widowhood) and more likely to be retired at the end of the six-year interval. Household income appears to decline from 1998 to 2004, whereas, there is no sign at the outset that overall housing wealth tends to decrease over time.‘1 Out-of-pocket medical expenses increase from 1998 to 2004, and so does the fraction of individuals with long-term care insurance. Our intent is understanding the housing wealth adjustments primarily of retirees. For analytical purposes, the sample of retirees we consider consists of the respondents in one- 4We convert all dollar amounts to 2004-dollars using the CPI-U deflator. 83 person households that are identified as partly or completely retired in both 1998 and 2004, and the respondents in two-person households where both spouses are partly or completely retired in both 1998 and 2004. This way, we have a sample size of 5,503 retirees.5 Of the total sample of initial homeowners (n=11,957), we observe 2,782 residential moves representing a 23.27% moving rate over the six-year period6. For the sample of retirees (n=5,503), there are 1,290 instances of a residential move representing a 23.44% moving rate. 3 Do the Elderly Reduce their Housing Wealth as they Age? We begin our analysis with Figure 3.1, which presents the mean and median changes in housing equity between 1998 and 2004 for (initial) 1998-homeowners. According to the life-cycle model, saving should be positive for individuals in their working years and negative when retired. Thus, we might expect wealth decumulation for the retirees, but not necessarily for the non-retirees. As such, we look into the changes in housing equity for the retirees and the non-retirees separately. The figure reveals that overall housing wealth is not spent down over the six-year period, not even for the retirees. However, the increase in housing equity is smaller for the retirees than for the non-retirees. As noted in the introduction, there are two ways to extract housing equity: moving and using a financial instrument. In what follows we first examine housing draw down via residential moving, as it has been the focus of the literature and is empirically more relevant. 3.1 Changes in Housing Wealth through Residential Moving The HRS asks movers about the reasons behind their residential moving. Respondents can report up to six reasons, though typically none reports more than two. Retiree-movers most 5Using the classification of complete retirement instead of both partial and complete re- tirement generates a sample of 4,147 observations. Results do not appear to be sensitive to the choice of the definition of retiree. 6The rate of moving reflects whether there has been any residential move for an individual. In other words, the moving rate does not capture multiple residential moves by an individual over this period. 84 prominently cite a reason that sounds something akin to downsizing: the intent of moving to less expensive or smaller homes. Consistent with the implication of the life—cycle model, this reason is much less important for the non-retirees in residential moving. For this group, employment related matters are more crucial in moving decisions. The reported reasons for moving, therefore, provide evidence that people move to downsize. They also indicate significant heterogeneity across individuals in moving behavior. The housing market experienced an overall surge during much of the period between 1998 and 2004, particularly from year-2000 (Sinai and Souleles, 2007). For this, we exam- ine the change in housing equity for non-movers along with that for the movers between 1998 to 2004. The group of non-movers provides us with a comparison group to contrast the movers’ housing adjustments with. After all, housing equity can be impacted for all homeowners — movers and non-movers — by housing price changes, mortgage repayments, reverse mortgages, home equity line of credits, as well as cutting back on maintenance. We plot the change in housing equity for retirees between 1998 and 2004 by age (age in 2004) in Figure 3.2. Panel A depicts the mean change in housing equity and Panel B displays the median change. Housing equity for retiree-movers declines from people’s mid- seventies if we consider the mean change and from their early-seventies if we consider the median change. Comparison of the changes in equity by age for all movers and movers who remain homeowners reveals that the decrease in housing equity among retiree-movers stems from initial homeowners that give up ownership altogether.7 Housing equity increases even among the oldest retirees in our sample that continue owning homes, regardless of whether they have made a residential move or not. Among movers there are some individuals who perhaps move because they feel forced to do so. For instance, certain individuals, particularly among those who do not have a spouse or a partner, may feel compelled to move into a nursing home or a retirement facility for requiring assistance with certain aspects in their daily living. It is useful to know if changes in housing equity might be different for those who feel forced to move compared to those who do not feel forced in the same way. Unfortunately, in our sample of retiree-movers between 7Since Figure 3.2 suggests that homeownership tends to decline with age, we present the tabulations for ownership rates by age in Appendix Figure A.3.2. As expected, the rate of owning gradually decreases with age, a finding that Sheiner and Weil (1992) and Heiss et al. (2005) report as the evidence for downsizing in later life. 85 years 1998—2004, there are very few cases where at least one of the spouses in a two—person household or the individual in a one-person household enters a nursing home. All these nursing home entrant observations are for ages 76 and older. On average, these respondents reduce their housing equity substantially more than the non-institutionalized retirees in the corresponding age groups. But the number of observations experiencing nursing home entry in each of these age groups is too small for us to infer much from it. Separating out these observations from the sample of retiree-movers does not alter the pattern of declining housing equity for the relatively older movers. 3.2 Changes in Housing Wealth through Equity Extraction In recent years, homeowners can tap into housing equity without having to sell their homes by taking advantage of financial instruments like home equity lines or credit (HELOC) or reverse mortgages. However, these markets still remain small, and during the sample period investigated in this paper (1998—2004), the use of these financial innovations were even narrower than in the last two-three years. The Health and Retirement Study (HRS) does not collect data on reverse mortgage use. But some information is available on the use of HELOC by homeowners. An increasing rate of HELOC access with age would be in line with the implication of the life-cycle model. Figure 3.3 shows the rate of HELOC access for retiree homeowners (that own in both 1998 and 2004) by age group. The access rate is relatively low in the sample and is gradually decreasing in age. In other words, the older homeowners — particularly the oldest ones in our sample — do not appear to make much use of this specific financial instrument.8 Moreover, in Figure 3.4 we see that those accessing HELOC, on average, have slightly higher housing equity in 1998 and experience a larger increase in housing equity between 1998 and 2004 than those not accessing HELOC.9 Thus, we do not find evidence that the elderly extract housing equity by making use of home equity lines of credit. 8The overall rate of home equity line of credit access among all retiree homeowners is 12.13%. 9The results are identical if we examine the median initial housing equity and the median change in housing equity instead of their respective means. 86 4 Why is there Relatively Little Reduction in Housing Wealth? In Section 3, we find little evidence of housing equity being drawn down overall. In this section, we examine why this appears to be the case. Do other types of wealth show any de- cumulation? Do certain individuals for whom we might expect to see declining wealth spend down housing equity? These questions are important in understanding whether the elderly regard housing wealth as a potential means of financing consumption during retirement. 4.1 Do the Retirees Reduce their Non-Housing Wealth as they Age? It is possible that the retirees view housing wealth differently from the rest of their asset hold- ings. After all, housing has a consumption value unlike any other types of wealth. If retirees spend down housing and non-housing wealth differently, then it might be indicative that the elderly generally do not want to withdraw wealth from housing equity for consumption smoothing at retirement. We look into changes in non-housing wealth between 1998 and 2004 for retirees by fo— cusing on net non-housing assets, which is the sum of the net value of secondary real estate (excluding primary residence), the net value of vehicles and businesses, IRA, Keogh accounts, stocks, mutual funds, and investment trusts, the value of checking, savings, or money market accounts, CD, government bonds, and T-bills, the net value of bonds and bond funds, and the net value of all other savings, less the value of other debts. The values of primary resi- dence, mortgages, and other home loans are not included. In the two panels of Figure 3.5, we present the mean (Panel A) and the median (Panel B) changes in net non-housing assets by age group. On average, non-housing wealth starts to decline from age 65. The median non-housing wealth falls throughout all ages. Housing wealth, therefore, appears different from non-housing wealth in that the retirees seem more likely to spend down non-housing than housing wealth. 87 4.2 The Heterogeneity in Housing Equity Reduction Even with little evidence of downsizing on average, we expect that certain individuals might have a greater need to extract housing wealth than others. In this section, we examine several potential sources of heterogeneity in housing equity adjustments during retirement. 4.2.1 Changes in Housing Equity by Reported Reasons for Moving We have seen in Table 3.1 that the intent to move to a smaller or less expensive home —— downsizing — is the leading reason for retirees in their moving decision. For these downsizing-movers, housing equity changes by an average of —$23,950.7; the median equity also changes by a similar magnitude of —$23,259.5.10 For the retirees moving for any other reason but downsizing, the mean and median changes in housing equity are $9,089.4 and —$19,701.2. In fact, there are two extreme outlier values in the change in housing equity among this group of retiree-movers (we mention these two observations in the context of Figure 3.2). Setting these two outlier values equal to the next highest value of change in housing equity in the data, we find the mean housing equity for these retiree-movers declining by —$13,319.0.11 In spite of the adjustments in the outliers, it appears that the retiree-movers who say they are moving to downsize reduce housing equity substantially more than the retiree-movers for whom the intent of downsizing is not important. To examine how the change in housing equity differs by reported reason for moving and by age, we plot in Figure 3.6 the mean and median changes in housing equity for downsizing-movers and non-downsizing-movers. The retiree-movers who move to downsize spend down housing equity nearly at all ages.12 The mean and median housing equity for the retiree-movers who move for other reasons also begin to decline at relatively older ages. Interestingly, once 10Of the retiree-movers (n=1,290), we have data on reasons for moving from 845 observa- tions (mentioned earlier in relation to Table 3.1). The mean and median changes in housing equity for whom we do not have data on reasons for moving are $25,834.4 and $6,953.4, respectively. 11For all retiree-movers (those that give up home-ownership and those that buy new houses), the mean change in housing equity is $9,866.2 (—$1,769.5, adjusting for the two outliers) and the median change in housing equity is —$8,112.3. (Note that in Figure 3.1 we consider the mean and median changes in housing equity for both movers and non-movers.) Retiree-movers for whom we have non-missing data on reasons for moving, the mean and median changes in housing equity are $956.5 (—$15,936.0, adjusting for the two outliers) and —$20,860. 1, respectively. 12Except that the mean and median housing equity increase very slightly for these movers at ages 76-80 and ages 66-70, respectively. 88 these movers begin extracting housing wealth their equity reductions are more sizable than the equity reductions observed for the downsizing-movers. But then the ages when housing equity declines for non-downsizing-movers are the same ages when housing wealth declines overall for the retiree-movers (Figure 3.2). All in all, retiree-movers moving for downsizing certainly reduce housing equity more and sooner if life than their counterparts who move for other reasons. 4.2.2 Do People with Low Wealth Reduce Housing Equity More? It might be that due to the consumption value of housing, housing wealth is spent down last. Thus, we might observe declining housing equity for those with low wealth — especially, non-housing wealth — but not necessarily for those who have relatively abundant wealth. To assess this point, we plot the changes in housing equity for retiree-movers by non-housing wealth quartiles and by age in Figure 3.7 — Panel A (for mean changes) and Panel B (for median changes). Indeed, retiree-movers in the highest non-housing wealth quartile tend to extract housing equity only at the oldest ages. Retiree-movers who are in the lowest quartile and in the second and third quartiles of non-housing wealth reduce their housing equity much sooner in life.13 4.2.3 Adverse Events, Alternative Insurance Availability, and Housing Equity Reduction Life events, such as, widowhood, divorce, nursing home entry, and prolonged or expensive medical treatments involving substantial out-of-pocket expenses, can influence housing draw down in retirement. Change in household structure leading to a smaller family size at the very least can make the existing housing appear too large. Illness or declining health may signal reduced life expectancy and accelerate decumulation of wealth. 1" Homeowners can self- 13Also, people with less household income (mostly, non-labor income, except for where the individuals are partly retired) may find it necessary to draw down housing equity. The relationship between household income and changes in housing equity by age is examined in Appendix Figure A.3.3. Results appear to closely mirror those reported with respect to non-housing assets. l4Certain health conditions might require individuals to migrate to regions with suitable climate or better availability of health care amenities. House moves from such considerations might result in increasing housing wealth. 89 insure against adverse health events in old age by saving in the house. In that case, having alternative forms of insurance, such as, children, or simply a long-term care insurance, may reduce the need to spend down housing wealth. Having children can potentially provide the elderly with alternative sources of monetary and non-monetary support. Parents with children may also be more willing to preserve housing equity out of bequest intentions. Either way, retirees without children may spend down housing equity more than their counterparts with children. To examine these many sources of heterogeneity in housing equity adjustments of retirees, we estimate a descriptive-type regression equation with the change in housing equity between 1998 and 2004 as the dependent variable. We estimate the equation for the retirees who are initially homeowners (who may or may not be homeowners in 2004), and also for retirees who are homeowners in both 1998 and 2004. We present the OLS estimates as well as the median regression estimates. The median regression estimates are likely to be less affected by the presence of outliers in the data. As regressors in the specification, we include a dummy variable, Moved, indicating whether the retiree has made any residential move between 1998 and 2004. The coefficient on this variable should indicate by how much more retiree-movers change their housing equity relative to non-movers over this period. Of course, if moving takes place to tap into housing equity, the estimated coefficient should be negative. In order to capture the importance of age in housing equity reductions, we include in the regression dummy variables for age, with the age group of 56—60 as the omitted category. We add a dummy variable for female to control for possible gender differences in housing wealth adjustments in retirement. Two dummy variables for education are included to examine if housing equity adjustments vary in education. We also add dummy variables representing household income and non—housing wealth quartiles. We include in the regression specification a dummy variable indicating spousal death or divorce and a dummy variable indicating if the retiree (respondent or the spouse) has been in relatively poor health condition from the beginning of the six-year period.15 More— over, we add an interaction term between whether the individual has moved and whether the individual has experienced spousal death/divorce. Similarly, we include an interac- 15We consider a composite health measure incorporating doctor-diagnosed serious medical conditions and limitations in activities of daily living (ADLs). 90 tion term Moved*Health Condition/ADL. The sum of the estimated coefficients on Spousal Death/Divorce and Moved*Spousal Death/Divorce gives the change in housing equity of movers who experience divorce or widowing in relation to movers without similar change in household structure. The sum of the coeflicients on Moved, Spousal Death/Divorce, and the interaction term Moved *Spousal Death/Divorce tells us the change in housing equity of movers who experience widowing or divorce in relation to non-movers without such experi- ence. Similarly, with respect to health conditions, the sum of the coefficients on Health Condi- tion/A DL and Moved *Health Condition/ADL gives the change in housing equity of movers who have had poor health in relation to movers without similar health conditions. And, the sum of the estimated coefficients on Moved, Health Condition/ADL, and Moved*Health Condition/ADL gives the change in housing equity of movers in poorer self/ family health in relation to non-movers without any major illness in the family. With respect to housing equity adjustments between movers and non-movers, the regres- sion results in Table 3.2 tell us the similar story as in Figure 3.2. Movers appear to reduce housing equity significantly more than the non-movers. Besides, comparison of the coeffi- cient estimates on Moved in the first two and the last two columns of Table 3.2 reveals that the significantly greater housing equity reduction of the retiree-movers is due to those who discontinue homeownership altogether. Continuing homeowners do not seem to reduce their housing equity post-move. In relation to the youngest age group of retirees in our sample, individuals ages 71 and older reduce housing equity significantly more. Retirees with more than high school graduate education increase housing equity substantially more than retirees with high school graduation. Those with relatively low household income and other wealth reduce housing equity substantially more compared to those who have the largest amounts of household income and other wealth, respectively. Retiree-movers experiencing spousal death or divorce reduce housing equity significantly more than movers not experiencing similar change in family composition. Moreover, com— pared to non-movers without any change in household structure, retiree-movers experiencing widowing or divorce reduce housing equity substantially and significantly more. These results hold whether we take into account the initial homeowners or continuing homeowners. The median housing equity declines more for retirees in poorer health than for retirees 91 in good health. The median reduction in equity of movers in poorer health is more sizable than the median reduction for movers without reported severe illnesses. On average, however, movers in poorer health do not reduce housing equity any more than movers without reported severe illnesses. Finally, movers in poor health reduce housing equity significantly more than non-movers in good health. None of these health effects on changing housing equity, however, are significant in the regressions for continuing homeowners.16 We also estimate the same regressions including dummy variables for whether the retiree has any children, any long-term care insurance, and a life insurance. Having long-term care insurance is negatively correlated with changes in housing equity. It might be that the retirees who perceive the need to have a long-term care insurance also need to extract housing equity more to deal with adverse health conditions. We do not find any statistically significant influence on housing equity adjustments with respect to having children, or a life insurance. 5 Summary and Concluding Remarks In this paper we examine whether retirees extract housing equity as part of a gradual decu- mulation of assets accumulated in preparation for retirement. For the period investigated, non-movers do not appear to systematically reduce housing equity by taking advantage of home equity lines of credit or reverse mortgages. But the median housing equity for movers declines starting at age 71, and the mean housing equity declines from age 76. The overall mean change in housing equity among retiree-movers is $9,866.2 (—$l,769.5, adjusting for two outliers) and the median change is —$8,112.3. Large reductions in housing equity, how- ever, are observed for homeowners who move and discontinue ownership. Typically, housing equity increases for retiree-movers who continue homeownership. Retirees are more likely to spend down their non-housing instead of housing wealth, which suggests that overall retirees might perceive housing equity differently from the rest of their asset holdings. But there is certainly evidence of heterogeneity in housing equity adjustments at retirement. Nearly a quarter of the retiree-movers report that they are moving to downsize, 16Except that the median equity reduction for movers in poor health is larger than the median reduction for non-movers in good health. 92 and they do. We examine whether certain individuals are more likely to extract housing equity because they may have a greater need to use that source of wealth. We find that retirees with low wealth as well as retirees with low income reduce housing equity significantly more than their respective counterparts. Additionally, retiree-movers experiencing widowing or divorce reduce housing equity substantially more than those without similar experience. The heterogeneity in housing equity draw down among the retirees offers evidence that at least certain groups of people treat housing as a fungible source of wealth that can be used to finance general consumption needs during retirement. But at the same time, we have seen that housing appears to serve predominantly as a consumption good rather than as a consumption-smoothing saving option for a large segment of the retirees. Our findings are, in fact, largely consistent with the existing evidence in the literature regarding downsizing in later life. This study does not disprove or bolster either side of the debate on the role of housing wealth in financing retirement needs. But it highlights that the choice of emphasis regarding which side of the debate holds is often reliant on how one chooses to interpret what is in the data. 93 Figure 3.1: Mean and Median Changes in Housing Equity Between 1998 and 2004 for 1998—Homeowners (in 2004—dollars) 70000 ] 60000- ] 50000 ,1 1 40000 ] 30000- 20000 10000 < 0- Retirees Non-Retirees [ [IMean Change in Housing Equity .Median Change in Housing Equity 1 Table 3.1: Movers’ Reported Reasons for Residential Moving % Reporting Reasons for Residential Moving Retirees N on-Retirees (n=845) (n=977) To Move to Less Expensive or Smaller Home 24.70 14.44 To be Near or With Child 21.96 13.69 Health Problems or Services Availability 20.58 4.30 Climate or Weather/ Leisure Activities 11 .17 9.30 To be Near or With Other Relatives/ Friends 8.97 6.87 Change in Marital Status 6.83 9.47 Work or Retirement Related Move 6.71 20.84 To Move to a Larger Home 4.84 10.16 Other 31.65 36.58 1. Sample consists of non-missing responses from 1,822 movers of the total 2,782 moving observations in the whole sample of the paper. 2. “Other” includes reasons such as: old neighborhood/ location bad; old home too expensive; natural disaster; new neighborhood/ location better; moved to retirement housing or complex; financial reasons; family problems; could not live by self; negative change in economic status of respondent or spouse/ partner (e.g., respondent or spouse/partner laid off or unemployed); positive change in economic status (e.g., received inheritance); to care for relative/ family member, to own instead of rent, etc. Clearly, some of these reasons are already implicit in the main reasons reported by the movers. 94 Figure 3.2: Changes in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age Panel A: Mean Change in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age1 120000 1mw04—————__-_«.s//\; -m_fi__L_ 2. -LL___ 80000 / \ 60000 \ A ] a» 40000 4- [ 20000 « 1 0 , ] _20000 56-60 61-65 66:70 71-75 76- 81-85 86-107 ] -40000 [ Age in 2004 :;———Non-Movei's—All Movers ""'—Movers Buying A New House] ] Panel B: Median Change in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age ] 50000» 40000-t-——-—ur-—---~-r— - -— n . .- -- [ 30000.- ] 20000 +- 10000 — : “’ 0 f -10000 . -20000 1 -30000 N -40000 ---v- -50000 ' Agein2004 1 l'_—N on-Movers _All Movers ...-Movers Buying a New House [ —_’ _J 1' Among retirees, there are two extreme outlier observations in changes in housing equity, both of which belong to the age group 71-75, producing the huge spikes in Figure 3.2 Panel A. These change amounts seem consistent with the education, household income, and other assets that these individuals report. Still, if we consider the mean change in equity for movers excluding those two observations, the mean change in equity for all movers is $7,187.1 and the mean change in equity for movers buying a new house is $27,890.9. We present in the Appendix Figure A.3.1 an alternative to Figure 3.2 Panel A, where the two extreme outlier values have been replaced by the next highest value for the change in housing equity (instead of excluding the observations). 95 Figure 3.3: Rate of Home Equity Line of Credit Access by Age (For Retiree Homeowners Throughout 1998—2004) 0.3 0.25 0.2 .\° 0.15 0.1 0.05 56-60 61 -65 66-70 71—75 76—80 81-85 86-107 Age in 2004 ]—Rate of Home Equity Line of Credit Access (For Retiree Homeowners Throughout 1998- 1' 2004) Figure 3.4: Initial Housing Equity and Change in Housing Equity For Non-Movers by Home Equity Line Of Credit (HELOC) Access 160,000.00 140,000.00 120,000.00 - , 100,000.00 - u 80,000.00 < 60,000.00 - ] 40,000.00 ] 20,000.00 . 0.00 [ Accesses HELOC Does Not Access HELOC fl—Inifial Housing Equity for Redree Non-Movers ] l ,IChange in Housing Equity for Retiree Non-Movers] 96 -10000 -20000 -30000 Figure 3.5: Changes in Non-Housing Wealth by Age Panel A: Mean Change in Non-Housing Wealth by Age 56-60 61-65 S mm] 1 Agein2004 44L '1 5 61-6 66-70 71-75 76:80 81—85, 86-107 -1000 —2000 -3000 ~ as -4000 -5000 -6000 -7000 ~ —8000 Agein2004 [—Median Chang? 18,1998599288 Y‘ieakh .1 97 Figure 3.6: Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Reported Reason of Moving and By Age Panel A: Mean Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Reported Reason of Moving and By Age: Movers who say they are moving to downsize versus movers who report other reasons r. ,__.__ _._- .... _._1 100000» 50000 -50000 —100000 . -150000 Agein 2004 ! [ F365;; for—Moving is Downsizing —Reason for Moving is NotDzwnEI; gj , .. -L L .H, ”mm ,__ ._ ______-L _ .__L_. ______L. Panel B: Median Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Reported Reason of Moving and By Age: Movers who say they are moving to downsize versus movers who report other reasons [ 10000 [ 0 ——M r T l I -10000 56—60 61.19/6625\71—75 J6-80 81-85 86-107 1 | -20000 - ,-___ . — ] 09 -30000 ] —40000 -——— — ] 50000 -,__, ] -600001 — l ] -70000 Agein2004 1 [”Reasonfor Moving is Down—sizing —Reason for Moving is Not Downsizing l 98 Figure 3.7: Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Non-Housing Wealth Quartiles and By Age Panel A: Mean Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Non-Housing Wealth Quartiles and By Age 150000 100000 «m _ __ .-__ __ _-_ __.__.__ __ 50000 — m4- 0 __ 56-60 66-70 71-75 - -50000 ~-— ———— - — -100000 Age in 2004 Non-Housing Wealth: Lowest Quartile """"-Non-Housing Wealth: 2nd and 3rd Quartiles — Non-Housing Wealth: Highest'Quartile _ _g_. k ,2h. 7 “MM -_ ___ _——’_. . . -._—__.__fi.fi__4 Panel B: Median Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Non—Housing Wealth Quartiles and By Age 140000 120000 ~ 100000 80000 v- -— 60000 5~ -- ~ 40000 — 20000 . 0 _ -20000 -40000 ~ -60000 Agein2004 f l Non-Housing Wealth: Lowesnt Quartile ”Non-Housing Wealth: 2nd and 3rd Quartiles, [— Non-Housing Wealth: Highest Quartile [ 99 Table 3.2: The Heteroggneity in HousinLEJruity Extraction Dependent Variable: Change in Housing Equity Between 1998 and 2004 Initial Homeowners: Always Homeowners: Retirees Retirees Independent Variables OLS Median OLS Median Regression Regression (1) (2) (3) (4) Moved -26,600.4* -20,870.7** - 1 4,5 89.5 -2,456.4 (10,766.7) (4,272.7) (11,352.8) (4,875.0) Ages 61—65 -25,782.6+ -19,335.6** -28,072.4+ -18,778.9* (14,239.6) (7,275.4) (14,689.6) (8,057.1) Ages 66—70 -16,027.5 -13,991.9* -17,320.6 -13,615.6+ (13,3298) (6,817.2) (13,747.0) (7,579.1) Ages 71 —75 -31,378.1* -19,849.7** -30,164.8* -17,806.1* (13,003.0) (6,738.9) (13,426.4) (7,497.5) Ages 76—80 -32,043.2* -20,457.3** -27,020.5* -17,109.3* (13,023.9) (6,751.6) (13,469.6) (7,518.1) Ages 71—85 41,080.0'" -21,551.7** -30,494.7* -16,839.7* (13,144.3) (6,800.2) (13,637.8) (7,587.4) Ages 86—107 47,707.2’" -28,193.0** -29,079.4* -20,135.6** (13,607.5) (6,936.7) (14,247.0) (7,784.9) Female -4,234.4 -287.4 -3,575.2 30.1 (3,784.0) (1,558.5) (3,935.7) (1,725.1) EducationHSG 12,833.2** 6,887.1** 15,255.8** 8,706.9** (4,271.5) (1,769.5) ' (4,441.9) (1,961.9) Household Income Lowest Quartile -23,769.3** -13,038.0** -31,435.3** -16,101.7** (7,198.2) (2,960.3) (7,471.1) (3,286.9) Second Quartile -20,191.3** -12,401.9** -24,940.8** -15,389.5** (6,369.7) (2,601.6) (6,587.4) (2,872.5) Third Quartile -15,367.9* -9,636.6** -22,093.1** -10,288.2** (6,048.1) (2,474.7) (6,199.8) (2,711.7) Non-Housing Wealth Lowest Quartile -19,217.6** -15,233.1** -15,745.3* -11,624.1** (6,535.9) (2,681.5) (6,877.8) (3,016.5) Second Quartile -18,808.1** -12,701.2** -15,023.1* -10,354.5** (5,718.5) (2,328.1) (5,969.4) (2,589.6) Third Quartile -3,003.6 -4,458.1* -3,665.7 4,362.74- (5,207.1) (2,142.7) (5,342.7) (2,349.3) Death / Divorce -1,870.1 1,569.5 1,070.6 4,208.0 (6,677.8) (2,671.4) (6,831.3) (2,916.1) Moved*Death / Divorce —52,999.0** -3l,871.7** -44,666.8** -22,415.9** (12,347.7) (4,881.5) (15,922.0) (6,646.0) 100 Table 3.2 Continued OLS Median OLS Median Regression Regression (1) (2) (3) (4) Health Condition / ADL -2,148.6 -7,327.6** -2,974.5 -7,379.9** (5,565.6) (2,264.7) (5,610.2) (2,437.7) Moved*Health Condition / ADL -8,021.5 -1,045.3 9,123.8 2,734.0 (1 1,637.0) (4,651.0) (12,510.5) (5,405.6) High Out-of-Pocket -8,763.6 187.7 -6,737.1 1,009.7 (5,920.9) (1,509.8) (6,420.1) (1,684.8) Living Children4 -1,749.4 -213.1 -2,441.0 1,042.2 (6,820.3) (2,958.2) (7,095.3) (2,732.6) Long-Term Care Insurance4 -12,l37.3* -5,764.2** -13,087.9** -6,199.5** (4,882.9) (2,035.8) (5,030.8) (1,884.2) Life Insurance4 -4,697.1 1,738.6 -7,229.8+ 1,587.9 (4,026.7) (1,703.1) (4,253.5) (1,611.1) Constant 98,343.8** 59,109.5** 100,603.3** 57,024.5** (14,491 .9) (7,242.0) (14,930.2) (8,036.1) Observations 5503 5503 4956 4956 R-squared 0.11 0.10 1. Standard errors in parentheses. + Significant at 10%; * Significant at 5%; ** Significant at 1%. 2. Omitted age group 56—60; omitted education group high school graduation. 3. Also omitted are the dummy variables for the highest quartile of household income and the highest quartile of net non-housing wealth. 4. The estimates for these variables are from a regression using a sample of 5445 observations in Columns (1) and (2), and a sample of 4913 observations in Columns (3) and (4). We lose several observations from the original samples due to missing data on these variables. The estimated coefficients for the other covariates are virtually unchanged in the regression using the somewhat smaller samples. 101 Appendzbc Table A.3.1: Sample Selection Criteria Number of Observations Total Number of Core Interview Obtained in 1998 21384 If Cohort and Age Eligible1 20002 93'540/0 If 2004 Interview Non-missingz 14380 67-25% If Homeowners in 1998 11983 56.04% If Race, Ethnicity, and Education Non-missing 11967 55.96% If Ownership in 2004 and Marital Status in 1998 a 2004 Non-missing3 11957 559% I - 1. Observations belong to the four cohorts in the Health and Retirement Study: AHEAD (1890- 1923), CODA (1924-1930), HRS (1931-1941), and War Babies (1942-1947). Note that in 2004 another cohort — the Early Baby Boomer (EBB) cohort (1948—1953) — was introduced in the Study, respondents from which are not part of our analyses. The 2004 survey in total interviews 15237 age-eligible respondents from the four cohorts. 3. 6,750 of these observations — 56.45% — are female. l" 102 Table A.3.2: Housing Wealth, Net Worth, and Demographic Features In 1998 and 2004 1998 2004 1998 2004 All Initial Homeowners Homeowners Both Periods n=11957 n=11083 Age of the Respondent 62.83 68.84 62.47 68.47 (9.16) (9.22) (8.96) (9.01) Less Than High School Graduation 20.58% 19.97% High School Graduation 35.54% 35.28% More Than High School Graduation 43.88% 44.75% Married or Partnered 74.11% 67.59% 75.73% 70.31% Respondent Partially or Completely Retired 53.82% 70.95% 52.83% 70.31% Respondent Completely Retired 45.52% 61.42% 44.46% 60.43% Respondent/ At Least One Spouse Partially or Completely Retired 64.18% 79.31% 63.49% 79.12% Respondent/ Both Spouses Partially or Completely Retired 43.96% 61.31% 42.60% 60.13% Respondent/ Both Spouses Completely Retired 34.69% 49.59% 33.31% 48.03% Home-Ownership 100% 92.84% 100% 100% Net Worth 433,777.8 548,661.6 445,916.7 576,501.2 (833,523.9) (1 ,941 ,638.0) (844,031 .6) (2,000,244.0) Household Income 72,627.9 63,811.6 74,786.0 65,888.3 (97,775.7) (102,415.6) (99,872.08) (102,079.9) Gross Housing Wealth 159,711.0 205,433.2 162,932.8 221 ,285.3 (360,086.3) (530,005.4) ' (371 ,899.6) (546,877.9) Housing Equity 125,190.1 172,827.3 127,912.5 186,164.2 (352,335.8) (510,094.3) (364,526.8) (527,060.4) Out of Pocket Medical Expenses 3,669.9 6,888.9 3,674.6 6,953.9 (6,900.1) (20,505.52) (6829.7) (20,9325) Any Child 93.10% 93.07% Has Life Insurance 83.97% 78.41% 84.72% 79.57% Has Lon -Term Care Insurance 13.92% 16.33% 14.00% 16.82% _ 1. Weighted tabulations are reported. 2. Standard deviations in parentheses. 3. Dollar amounts in year-2004 3 (CPI-U deflator). 103 Figure A.3.1: Mean Change in Housing Equity for Retirees by Age (Adjusting for the Two Extreme Outlier Values for Change in Housing Equity) ] l [ 100000 80000 1 - 60000 . 40000 20000 < O , -20000 < —40000 _56—60 61-65%! 66-70 _71-75 76-.. 81-85 86.107 Agein2004 — Non-Movers All Movers """""Movers Buying A New HOLE Note: The two extreme outlier values of change in housing equip for movers are replaced by the next highest value of housing equity change in the sample of retirees. Figure A.3.2: Rate of Home-Ownership in 2004 for 1998-Homeowners By Age 96 100 95 90 85 80 4» 75 70 56-60 66—70 71-75 76-80 Agein2004 61-65 81-85 86-107 ] ] P-Rate of Hpmeownership in 2004 forBetirees 104 Figure A.3.3: Changes in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Total Household Income Quartiles and By Age Panel A: Mean Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Total Household Income Quartiles and By Age 80000 60000 40000 , , \ fi 20000 -20000 -40000 w -60000 -80000 Agein2004 —Total Household Income: Lowest Quartile ] "'"'""Total Household Income: 2nd and 3rd Quartiles _ Total Household Income: Highest Quartile Panel B: Median Change in Housing Equity among Retiree Movers By Total Household Income Quartiles and By Age 80000 60000 40000 ~~ 20000 -20000 -40000 -60000 Age in 2004 l Total Household Income: Lowest Quartile ' Total Household Income: 2nd and 3rd Quartiles; .— Total Household Income: Highest Quartile [ 105 References [1] [21 [61 [7] [91 [101 [11] [12] [13] [14] Aizcorbe, A. M., A. B. Kennickell, and K. B. Moore. 2003. “Recent Changes in US. Family Finances: Evidence from the 1998 and 2001 Survey of Consumer Finances”. Federal Reserve Bulletin; Vol. 89, No. 1: pp. 1-29. Apgar, W. C. and Z. Xiao Di. 2006. “Housing Wealth and Retirement Savings: Enhanc- ing Financial Security for Older Americans”. In CLark, G. L., A. H. Munnell, and J. M. Orszag edited Oxford Handbook of Pensions and Retirement Income. Oxford University Press. Diamond, P. and J. Hausman. 1984. “Individual Retirement and Savings Behavior”. Journal or Public Economics: Vol. 23 (Feb-Mar): pp. 81-114. Feinstein, J. and D. McFadden. 1989. “The Dynamics of Housing Demand by the El- derly: Wealth, Cash Flow, and Demographic Effects”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Eco- nomics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Heiss, F., M. Hurd, and A. B6rch-Supan. 2005. “Healthy, Wealthy and Knowing Where to Live: Predicted Trajectories of Health, Wealth and Living Arrangements Among the Oldest Old”. In Wise, D. A. edited Analyses in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Hurd, M. D. and D. A. Wise. 1989. “The Wealth and Poverty of Widows”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Kennickell, A. B. and J. Shack-Marquez. 1992. “Changes in Family Finances From 1983 to 1989: Evidence From the Survey of Consumer Finances”. Federal Reserve Bulletin; Vol. 78(1): pp. 1-18. Merrill, S. R. 1984. “Home Equity and the Elderly”. In Aaron, H. and G. Burtless edited Retirement and Economic Behavior: pp. 197—225. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution. Modigliani, F. 1986. “Life Cycle, Individual Thrift, and the Wealth of Nations”. Amer- ican Economic Review: 76 (3), pp. 297-313. Modigliani, F. and F. Brumberg. 1954. “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Crosssection Data”. In Kurihara, K. K. edited Post-Keynesian Economics. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press. Poterba, J. M. and A. A. Samwick. 2001. “Household Portfolio Allocation Over the Life Cycle. In Ogura, S., T. Tachinbanaki, and D. A. Wise edited Aging Issues in the US and Japan. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Sheiner, L. and D. Weil. 1992. “The Housing Wealth of the Aged”. NBER Working Paper No. w4115. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Sinai, T. M. and N. S. Souleles. 2007. “Net Worth and Housing Equity in Retirement”. NBER Working Paper No. wl3693. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. Skinner, J. 1996. “Is Housing Wealth a Sideshow?” In Wise D. A. edited Advances in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. 106 6. IIIIIIIOII'I I [ll ltl'v 8‘! ‘. is. [15] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 2004. “Aging and Housing Equity: Another Look”. In Wise, D. A. edited Perspectives on the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. [16] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 1990. “But They Don’t Want to Reduce Housing Equity”. In Wise, D. A. edited Issues in the Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. ‘ [17] Venti, S. F. and D. A. Wise. 1989. “Aging, Moving and Housing Wealth”. In Wise, D. A. edited The Economics of Aging; Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. 107 ITY LIBRARIES :4 R E V U MICHIGAN 57A IE [I] I [M] l [[l 7397 [1' ill] [Ill] 1293 02956 3