ABSTRACT ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND THE CULTURE OF MODERN DEMOCRACY: A STUDY OF DEVELOPMENTAL PROCESSES AMONG COSTA RICAN STUDENTS By Hugh Montgomery Clark Socio-economic development is frequently assumed to be associated with "modernization" of political culture. To examine this proposition the author gathered questionnaire data from 734 Costa Rican high school students, in 1958. Respondents were segregated into three groups according to the level of economic development of region of residence. The data analysis indicates no consistent support for the assumption that cultural modernization is associated with economic development in a continuous way when the former is measured among a relatively elite (student) population. The relationships which result include both negative and mildly positive significant relationships of developmental factors to cultural factors, but for the most part relationships failed to attain statistical significance. However, the attempt to explain systematic variations which do appear, by introduction of control variables produces results which suggest that socio-economic development is very much related to cultural modernity, but that the relationship are far more complex than expected. The striking fact is that the relationships between control variables (particularly social status and traditionalism of general belief pat- terns) and a wide-range of dependent variables (political attitudes generally said to be characteristic of "modern" political cultures —HughLClark_w including efficacy, trust, etc) do not remain constant among the regions. That is, the relationships among control and dependent variable, vary among levels of the independent variable (regional development), rather than providing an "explanation" of variance associated with the dependent variable. The factor "traditionalism" of general cultural belief patterns appears to provide a partial explanation for the varying relationships.1 In Costa'Rica, the less developed a region, the more culturally tradi- tional its students. Moreover, to take the most striking example of this logic it is among highly traditional persons of all regions that social status has its strongest impact on political attitudes. Apparently the assumption that status carries with it political influence, prevails only where stratification remains rigid among persons who accept a traditional world view, including ascriptive recruitment criteria. In short, the impact of socio-economic development is primarily manifest in its impact on general cultural values, and only secondarily on political attitudes. Development appears to be a social force which produces a redefinition of general cultural beliefs as a people moves from a state of agrarian rural society to that of industrial metropolitan society. The meaning of social characteristics and socialization processes across the lines of developmental levels is not constant. Thus predictions of the political impact of variables such as social status must be redrawn with the crossing of spatial or temporal lines of variant development, at least when it is known “W; Hugh Clark that traditional belief patterns distinguish the less from the more developed regions. 1David Smith and Alex Inkeles, "The OM Scale: A Comparative Socio-Psychological measure of Individual Modernity," Sociometry, (December, 1966), pp. 353-377. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND THE CULTURE OF MODERN DEMOCRACY: A STUDY OF DEVELOPMENTAL PROCESSES AMONG COSTA RICAN STUDENTS By Hugh Montgomery Clark A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 1972 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS As is true of most social survey studies, the list of adknow- ledgments which should be made is totally unmanageable. Special thanks go to my committee for overseeing the work of an obdurate student, and to Sr. Eugenio Fonseca, Director of the Department of the Sciences of Han at the University of Costa Rica who provided invaluable on-the- scene advice. Without the assistance of Sr. Rafael Villegas Antillon, the study would have been completely impossible. His encouragement and skillful expediting, very simply, made this work possible. 11 Chapter TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I 0 INTRODUCTION 0 O O O O O O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 1 Part I. Part II. The Political Cultures of Mbdernity andDemocraCy..................1 The Relationship of Attitudes to System Performance Empirical Evidence Operationalization and Specification of Cultural Factors to be Studied: Modern and Democratic Aspects of Political Culture Attitudes and Behaviors Related to Political Participation Attitudes Toward National Institutions and Their Components Behavioral Dimensions of Participation Attitudes which Establish Parameters of Legitimate Action Questionnaire Construction and Administration, Practical Aspects The Associations of Socio-Economic Development With the Growth of the Cultures of Modernity AndDemocraCYeeeeeeeeeeeeeeeeee19 Socio—Economic Development as Associated With Democratic Forms of Modernity The Within-System Study of variation in Political Culture An Alternative Perspective on the Relation- ship Between Development and Modern Democratic Culture Summary Footnotes, Chapter I II. COSTA RICA: TRANSITIONAL DEMOCRACY AND RESEARCH SITE. . . 36 Sampling Procedure The Capital Cities and variation in Economic Development Center and Periphery: Explaining Ecological Correlation with Individual Variables Summary Footnotes, Chapter II iii AAA-cl'l‘lllll'l' Chapter Page III. REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT AND STUDENT ATTITUDES TOWARD MODERN FORMS OF POLITICAL BEHAVIOR. . . . . . . . . . . 72 Regional Location and the Culture of Modern Political Participation Pre-Citizen Competence and Developmental Factors Status Traditionalism Socialization Process: Participatory Role Playing in the Family Developmental Variables and the Expectation Of Equal Treatment by Bureaucratic Authorities Conclusions Footnotes, Chapter III IV. REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT AND STUDENT ATTITUDES TOWARD DEMOCRATIC FORMS OF POLITICAL PROCESS . . . . . . . . . 125 Center-Periphery and the Bivariate Relationship to the Procedural Norms Of Democracy Social Status, the Regions, and the Spread of Democratic Norms Traditionalism Participant Role Playing in the Family And the Development of the norms of Democracy Conclusions Footnotes, Chapter IV V. CONCLUSIONS: SEVERAL HYPOTHESES AND A NUMBER OF SPECULATIONS O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 1 57 Changing Environmental Factors and the Revision of Developmental Theory Propositions Derived from the Data Summation Footnotes, Chapter V BELImRA-PHY O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 1 7‘ APPmm. O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 187 iv Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 5-1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 LIST OF TABLES Demographic/political characteristics of Costa Rican Provinces Rank order average standard deviation from mean and trichotomous grouping of the seven provincial capitals on selected indices of socio-economic development Center-periphery index to social status Occupation for respondent's father, grandfather and self, as reported by respondent Center-periphery dimension to traditionalism index Centerbperiphery dimension to participant role playing experiences in family decision making Gamma coefficients for relationship of center-periphery regional development index to modern political attitudes Center periphery to pre-citizen competence Center~periphery index to expectation of equal treatment Social status to pre-citizen competence, controlled for center-periphery index Traditionalism to pre-citizen competence controlled for center-periphery index Social status to traditionalism controlled for center- periphery dimension Participant role playing in the family to pre-citizen competence controlled for centerbperiphery index Social status to expectation of equal treatment, con— trolled for centerbperiphery index Social status to expectation of equal treatment by page 55 58 61 65 69 76 78 82 94 102 106 110 114 administrative authorities, controlled for traditionalism118 and center-periphery index page Table 4.1 Relationship between center-periphery index and selected procedural norms of democracy 128 Table 4.2 Social status to democratic values, controlled for centerbperiphery index 135 Table 4.3 Traditionalism to democratic values, controlled for center-periphery index 139 Table 4.4 Traditionalism to democratic values, controlled for social status and center-periphery index 142 Table 4.5 Participant role playing in family decisions to belief that elections ought to be regularly scheduled, controlled fer center-periphery index 147 Table 4.6 Role playing in family decisions to support for regular elections, controlled for traditionalism and centeruperiphery index 149 Table 4.6 (Cont'd) 150 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 2.1 Political and physical map of Costa Rica 38 vi CHMPTER I INTRODUCTION Part I The Political Cultures Of Modernity and Democracy various authors have discussed the notion that there exist universal cultural prerequisites to democracy. ‘With a number of specific differences, but with a similar logic among them, scholars from Hannheim to Lasswell to Pye argue that modern or democratic behavior presupposes widespread existence of personality traits which support both the tendency of men to participate in politics and the reasons (or unconscious inhibitions) for which they moderate their behavior.1 They argue, with variations in the precise connotations of the attitudes they are discussing, that both self confidence which extends into social and political matters, and a pervasive sense of "faith in others” are necessary components of the "democratic personality." Mannheim suggests that the cooperative spirit required cannot exist in the presence of severe status insecurity.2 Pye suggests that generalized ”social trust" is the essential ingredient which enables persons to act together in the impersonal organizations which are said to be the 3 basis of modern (pluralist) democracy. In turn, Lasswell argues that the "democratic citizen” must possess an "open ego" which enables him to relate to others on a basis of trust in their intentions, and to utilize his potentialities for participation to the fullest degree.4 Conversely, Inkeles argues that the totalitarian man.will have exaggerated faith in leaders, an uncommon hatred of outsiders and deviants, "excessive projection of guilt and hostility," suspicion and distrust, dogmatism and rigidity.5 These are highly complex psycho-cultural characteristics, and even if the obstacles to survey research were not so great in totalitarian systems, would be extremely difficult to cperaticnalize. This is also true of the amorphous concept "open ego" discussed by Lasswell. The difficulties with utilization of these concepts as theoretical undergirdings of the culture of democracy are more than practical, however. There are at least two fundamental difficulties which must be clarified. One ought, first, to question whether the norms which these and other authors have related to democracy in particular, are not more likely to be related to political modernity in general, regardless of its specific form, democratic at one extreme and totalitarian at the other. Furthermore in this respect, one may ask whether the idealized characteristics of totalitarian and democratic personalities and cultures discussed by these authors are not strongly related to cold war mental sets regarding the relative perversity of national enemies, and not to the essential relationships between institutions and the human psyche. Secondly, one must consider the fundamental question of whether it is valid to assume that the study of attitudes and culture provides any meaningful information about a political system at all. ThOBO questions require extended consideration. The Cultures of'nodernity and of Democgggy A modern political system is characterized by high levels of individual and group participation in political processes, by high levels of contact between individuals and the administrative processes of national regimes, by administrative and elite recruitment processes which are relatively achievement oriented and impersonal. Thus modern systems tend also to be characterized by considerable mass political equality when contrasted with traditional regimes. Therefore, if one assumes that a population's attitudes must be roughly consistent with the individual and group behaviors required for a stable, predictable existence in the institutional setting in which they live, then a modern polity, (in an institutional sense) must exist in a cultural milieu which supports individual and group participation by the maximum number of persons in political affairs. The democratic variant of the modern political system requires that political participation take certain forms which avoid extreme elite domination of masses, and domination of one elite segment over others to the extent that no competition for the exercise of power or the expression of opposing political views is possible. That is the existence of democracy requires that the initiatives of competing elites and their ability to attain power peacefully by appeal for mass support, must be protected. In the western experience this has usually meant an emphasis on choice among competing elites in regular elections and the protection of the rights of opposition elites to seek and wield power. This is the case not only for reasons of what is widely assumed in the west to constitute "justice,” but more fundamentally because it is by the maintenance of the openness of the political process that the democratic version of modern politics serves its function as a forum or setting in which conflict can be peacefully resolved. If this image appears a bit idealized, it is nevertheless the approxi- mate ideal to which most democratic-leaning transitional nations appear to be striving. This is certainly true in the Costa Rican Case. In part, therefore, the culture of democracy in the modern era must be characterized by an awareness on the part of politically active sectors of the population that it is necessary for them and legally constituted authorities to follow established legal procedures for providing opportunities for challenge from oppositionists by appeal for mass support. It is probable that many other factors of a cultural nature are also necessary to the maintenance of stable modern democracy. Perhaps the "open ego" discussed by Lasswell, a low level of conceptual rigidity or dogmatism or other factors more deeply rooted in the personality than beliefs about desirable and necessary operating pro- cedures, are also requirements of the fully democratic culture. To determine the full extent of such factors, however, would involve research far beyond the more modest scope of this paper, and well beyond the intent of the author. my intention is more simply, to examine the relationships between developmental factors and some cultural factors which we may agree are distinctly democratic in the Costa Rican context. Thus a pragmatic approach will be followed here which will focus on the procedural norms of democracy and leave the more abstract components of the democratic culture to future research. This approach will also make a general distinction between norms sup- portive of democratic, and those supportive of modern behaviors. Admittedhythe distinction is not entirely perfect, for there exists some overlap between the categories. However it is a useful distinction for organizing ones thoughts about political culture in transitional systems. To take an example of this distinction, we may refer first to Pye's work. If he is correct in his assertion that social trust is a necessary cultural ingredient for the operation of impersonal political organizations on a stable, effective basis, then he has given a prescription which applies equally well to the success of parties and bureaucracy in a totalitarian or a democratic system.6 Similarly, if status insecurity is the enemy of political stability and moderated conflict in a democracy, as Mannheim argues, there is no reason to assume that it will not also be so in a totalitarian system.7 Even the belief that the institutions and elites of the political system.will in some way respond to his needs and expressed desires, at least in the long run, cannot be without a variant in the citizen of a totalitarian system unless elites are willing and able to utilize repression as a constant tactic, or unless the ideology of self sacrifice for national ends is utterly effective. In contrast, the belief that the manner in which elite responsive- ness to mass needs and desires is to be maintained by protection of the opposition and maintenance of its right to seek power in a non- violent manner by electoral appeal to mass publics is compatible only with the democratic style of politics as I have defined it. To summarize, the culture of modern democracy appears to be composed of two reasonably distinct elements. Of these, one supports individual and group participation in the political institutions of mobilized societies in general. The other establishes parameters of procedure within which political participation must be conducted. In short, it defines legitimate political participation and provides a cultural inertia which helps assure the continuence of democratic forms of participation. Objection may be raised to the position that support for the procedural norms of democracy is a factor of any importance in maintenance of a democratic system. It is widely known that citizens of the United States, as a mass, do not show a high frequency of support for "civil liberties" or the democratic processes I am here arguing are necessary components of a democratic culture. Yet we normally consider the United States to be a relatively democratic system.8 It would seem that firm insistence on the maintenance of these parameters cannot be expected of the mass public which is unlikely to be educated in the niceties of self limitation for the common good. Hewever, if a democracy is to maintain its essential procedures of peaceful conflict resolution, freedom of speech and press for the opposition and freedom for the opposition to contest elections, it would appear that the politically active segments of the population -— i.e. the middle and upper middle classes of a society in particular - must be aware of the need for such limitations and insist on their application. If this elite fails to grasp the essential rules of the democratic political process, it seems likely that little stability or durability of those processes can be expected, especially in the absence of a mass committment to those values. It is in part for this reason that I am concerned here not with the attitudes of a mass population, but with those of an elite and near-elite sample. Thus we are dealing with persons whose conduct as adults will be crucial to the maintenance of democracy. Denton maintains that among present elitesin Costa Rica, a general consensus exists on the norms of democratic process.9 This agreement was forged in the bloody but decisive victory of the Social Democrats and their allies in the civil war of 1948, and the subse- quent consolidation of their gains by the reinforcement of democratic institutions, disbanding of the national army, and in particular, the maintenance of democratic elections. The question, then, is to what extent this elite has been successful in infusing the socialization process, and‘thus new genera- tions of elites, with these norms. And to what extent have processes of socio-economic development enhanced or obstructed their efforts at not only passing'democratic norms on intergenerationally, but also extending'them.throughout the more traditional areas of the nation? The Relationship of Attitudes to System Performance The second objection.which may be raised to the cultural approach utilized in this paper is that it may not be valid to assume that in fact public attitudes have an important influence on system level functions. The difficulty is that while the logic of this assumption is quite clear, it is difficult to provide convincing empirical evidence to demonstrate its validity. If one conceives of political institutions as sets of customary and legal parameters in which political participation occurs,then it is also reasonable to assume that institutional stability can exist only when behaviors which are consistent with the "structure” of those institutions characterize the population. ‘without such consistency either the institutions or the behaviors must change. Further, unless an exogenous factor such as terror, group pressure for social conformity, strong tangible incentives, or other external factor prevents it, attitudes - which are predispositions to react to, i.e. behave toward, objects in given.ways - will be an important factor in determining behavior. Taken in the aggregate as ”culture,” then, attitudes will help shape the mass behaviors which in turn alter or maintain the institutional forms of a system. Egpirical Evidence 'Voting studies and other studies based on mass survey research hare demonstrated rather conVincingly that even in non-laboratory situations attitudes have an observable influence in shaping individual behaviors. The American Voter, for example, shows, among other things, that persons with high scores of "political efficacy" tend to be more participant in politics than persons with low scores.10 Similarly, V. O. Key's secondary analysis of much of the SRC data indicates that a number of attitudes are regularly associated with certain political behaviors, particularly voting, but also with other types of political participation.11 These works are exemplary of a host of materials which hays demonstrated relationships among opinions, attitudes and behaviors.12 fibre problematic is the relationship which attitudes bear to the functioning of total political systems. The major work to date which brings empirical evidence to bear on this question is the inic Culture.13 In that work the authors designate five nations, on a priori grounds, as democracies. Subsequently they examine the mass attitudes, or "political cultures," which are associated with such systems. In many ways this is an informative design, but it cannot be said to provide a logical demonstration that similar systems could not exist with other sets of attitudinal configurations, or that dissimilar watems could not exist with precisely the same atti- tudinal characteristics. Even from an inductive perspective, their work cannot be taken to be a satisfying "proof” that the cultural characteristics studied are actually necessary conditions for the existence of the particular structures and styles of politics of democratic systems. The sample is simply too small and too western.14 On the other’hand, however, neither can one say that their results are inconsistent with the assumption that there must exist rough ”congruence" or consistency between institutions and political cultures to maintain stability of either. Thus, if this assumption cannot easily be accepted as definitive or entirely valid, neither need it be rejected out of hand. Rather, given the inherent logic of the arguments supporting it, one may well wish to elaborate upon it and in.the meantime utilize it for'heuristic purposes under the assumption that such usage will ultimately expose its strengths or weaknesses indirectly by resulting in correct or incorrect predictions of system level change. Despite the lack of any perfect evidence to indicate that the assumption of cultural and institutional congruence is valid, the belief that cultural attributes must bear an important relationship to system structure and process is so compelling that students of political culture as renown and diverse as‘Msnnheim, Lasswell, Eckstein, and Brinton have suggested that certain attitudes, sets 10 of attitudes, or distributions of attitudes, are a §_i_1_1_e_ qua Egg of democracy or stable political systems of other types.15 While their work has been largely nonpempirical, some researchers have utilized quantitative technique to investigate the relationships involved. An appropriate example is the work of Goldrich relating legitimacy orientations of pre-elites in Panama and Costa Rica to the levels of political stability in those nations in the 1960's.16 Mere recently, in another study dealing with the attitudes of youth, Inglehart and Abramson have examined the relationship of system affect in children to the nature of symbols of national executive power, suggesting implicitly a causal loop in which the attitudes which support the maintenance of such institutions, also are in part a product of them.17 Thus some researchers other than Almond and Verba have utilized the assumptions in question to useful purpose. One means utilized by many researchers to reduce the risk that the attitudes under study bear no real relationship to the political system is the concentration on elites. Thus Goldrich studied the "Sons of the Establishment” of Costa Rica and Panama.18 LeVine has examined only the Amhara of Ethiopia.19 Pye has dealt only with the elites of the bureaucracy and parties of Burma.20 The study of such a select group of a population limits the scope of a study to be sure, but it also gives additional confidence that the attitudes or cultural attributes of the sample studied are in fact related to the operations of the political system. In the present study it will be assumed that the attitudes of the Costa Rican elite and near elite are a significant force in shaping their individual behavior and that their behavior in turn is influential in shaping 11 the actions of others and in maintaining or reshaping the "structures" of politics. Operationalization and Specification of Cultural Factors to be Studied: ‘Modern and Democratic Aspects of Political Culture The final sets of dependent variables selected for study are listed in Figure 1.1. With two exceptions, the variables listed under the category of attitudes related to political participation are fully compatible with the structures and processes of totalitarian systems, as previously argued. The exceptions to this rule are pre- citizen competence and trust of the political parties. Pro-citizen competence is here defined operationally as the belief that one can have an impact on the decisions of public officials, particularly in the case of disagreement with a policy they are consider- ing.21 Thus it assumes real lines of access to decisional processes on the part of persons of the status of these students. Few democratic systems could be expected to fully meet the institutional ideal in this regard. However, a totalitarian system would presumably militate against it, meeting the need for feedback from the public in other ways. The second exception is "partisan trust," or the belief that the political parties can be trusted not to endanger the country. Certainly a totalitarian system would require an analogous form of public confidence in the capabilities and intent of the single party which is typically a characteristic of such systems. However, this attitude would be of a different order than the one discussed here which allows for selective distrust of one or more of the several major political parties.22 12 A. Attitudes and Behaviors Related to Political Participation23 l. Attitudes toward self assertive political and social actions of self and others a. pre-citizen competence b. sense of personal effectiveness c. generalized social trust 2. Attitudes toward system institutions and components a. assessment of the general beneficiality of national government b. trust of politicians to be honest and to work for the general wellbeing of the nation c. trust of the political parties not to endanger the country d. expectation of equal treatment by administrative officials 3. Behavioral dimensions of participation a. interest in and attention to political news b. political knowledge score B. Parameters of Legitimate Participation 1. Democratic values in general (support for free speech for the opposition, regular elections, universal suffrage, free opposition press) 2. Government should not be allowed to postpone elections regardless of how good a job it may be doing With this introduction to the general themes to be examined here, it will be useful to examine the dimensions of the modern democratic political culture, as I have defined it operationally, in more detail. 1. Attitudes and behaviors related to political participation and modern political behavior in general: Self assertive political and social actions of self and others The components of one's view of himself as a participant in the political life of a nation include a sense of political 13 effectiveness and a more generalized sense of personal effectiveness. The former dimension is an adaptation from the subjective competence scale of Almond and Verba.24 Because that scale is related to adult political roles, the respondents in my study, being all students, were asked to imagine themselves in their future adult roles as political participants, and to guage the likely nature and effect of their political behavior at that time. The result was a series of items which combined by the method suggested by Ford into a satisfactory Guttman scale with r a 94.9.25 Unfortunately, for practical reasons adequate pre-testing was not possible, and in the final tabulation, the projective questions proved too difficult for about 40-45% of the sample to answer. However, the inability to answer the questions posed is unrelated to the primary independent variable (level of socio—economic development of region of residence), and thus appears to have had little distorting effect on the final results. It does, however, limit the scope of data analysis by limiting the number of cases available to work with in several instances in which further analysis might have been useful. It is clearly important to study attitudes of political competence, for this dimension, or a variant such as "efficacy," have been widely reported to be positively related to levels of political participation.26 With regard to the second variable under consideration, sense of personal effectiveness, one would be hard pressed to support the contention that political behavior would be strongly related to its scale scores, since many variables intervene between such a general attitude and specific political behaviors. Yet the authors of the American voter have shown that this general sense of personal effectiveness 14 is related to political efficacy which is in turn related to political participation.27 moreover, it is desirable, in dealing with a youthful sample especially, not to confine oneself to the study of variables which, like pre-citizen competence, are directly political in the sense that they relate to specific political actions and specific political institutions. Rather, one ought to look beyond them and examine attitudes which have less specific referents and are more "central" to the personality structure. Broadening the concept in this way helps to free the variable from the problem of being bound to specific objects such as political institutions toward which one's views and feelings may change with the experiences of adult roles. Thus examination of such a general variable gives an opportunity to examine an attitude which is less likely than the more specific pre- citizen competence to change with the assumption in the near future of adult roles by the respondents in the sample used here. A series of four items was used to tap this dimension. The items were adapted from the Minnesota Multi-phasic Personality Inventory items. They combined into a satisfactory Guttman scale according to the method suggested by Ford, with a coefficient of reproducibility of 91.4.28 Both of the above variables are supportive of political activity. Yet, as has been pointed out several times, participation alone does not constitute modern political behavior. A moderate style of politics is also required, a style which maintains nonaviolent, stable processes of conflict resolution. Pye's caution should be recalled, that high participation.without substantial social trust 15 is likely to lead to severe conflict.29 Moreover such attitudes of trust can be assumed to comprise part of the general feeling of tolerance which is surely as essential to the maintenance of the rights of minorities and oppositionists as the procedural guarantees discussed previously. 2. Attitudes toward national institutions and their components As Goldrich points out, the attitudes of elites, including young elites, toward the legitimacy of political institutions is a critical factor in determining the continuation or loss of political stability.30 One way to examine the attitudes of young elites toward the institutions and personnel of national institutions is to ask them whether they consider the "government of the Republic" to be generally beneficial or not. Also, it is well to continue with questions regarding major specific components of the national regime, for the national government may receive support as a.matter of national feeling despite waning confidence. In this case I have examined the respondent's attitudes toward ”politicians" and toward the political parties. Can the politicians be trusted to be honest and to work in behalf of the general welfare (bienestar)? Can the parties be trusted not to endanger the country? (For the latter dimension each party is examined separately and the scores summarized in an index score). While students of survey research have come to expect a certain amount of public cynicism about parties and politicians, it would seem important that such cynicism.not be excessive, nor that it lead to questionning of the legitimacy of the national regime itself. For if this were to occur, it would become impossible to maintain 16 stable political operations for a long period of time without coercion of a public which had lost its confidence in the government. Ehre- over, it would appear important that where cynicism does exist, that it be distributed in a fairly random manner, not systematically among the regions of the country or other social groups. For a systematic distribution of trust of governmental agents to arise would indicate signs of developing regional or group conflict. Finally, the citizen does not most regularly relate to the input side of governing processes in a direct experiential way, but with the administrative or output side. Thus it is of some importance to examine one of the most critical of beliefs about modern administra- tive agencies: Does the respondent expect equal treatment? Or does he anticipate favorable or unfavorable discrimination? And when expectation of unequal treatment does exist, is it systematically concentrated in the less developed areas of a country? One item is used for this purpose. 5. Behavioral dimensions of participation Under the final category of cultural characteristics related to participation of a general nature are two behavioral dimensions directly related to the "interest" and "information" dimensions of Inkeles' modernity schema previously discussed. Does the respondent pay attention to political news? Is he interested in it? Can he answer several simple questions about national politics, including the naming of several present and past cabinet official and a presidential candidate, and the terms of office of the president and legislators? The "interest and attention” dimension is a simple 17 additive index of two items. The political knowledge score is a composite score of the respondent's ability to answer the five questions posed. 4. Attitudes which establish the parameters of legitimate political action These dimensions have been substantially discussed on previous pages, and that discussion require little reiteration here. Suffice it to say that democracy as I have defined it, requires an ability of the general populace to exert control over the selection of elites, usually by means of elections. ‘Moreover, it requires that real choice be available, a requirement which necessitates guarantees of free expression and electoral participation by the opposition. Thus a general index of democratic values was constructed based upon freedoms of speech and press and the nature of elections as regular and universal in participation. Because the maintenance of regular elections became the critical issue which sparked the 1948 civil war, and is such a crucial factor in the establishment of democratic processes in much of Latin.America, the item dealing with regular elections is also reported separately from the index of democratic values of which it is a part. Questionnaire Construction and Administration,_Practical Aspects Because time for pre-testing was severely limited for practical reasons (ending of the school year), I could not hope to develop an extensive number of original items to test these many dimensions. Consequently, I relied for about 8Q% of the questions on survey items which had previously been used in major surveys, and had 18 been protested and used in Spanish. Especially useful sources were Almond and verba's Civic Culture questionnaire and the questionnaire used by Goldrich in his Sons of the Establishment.31 When translation was necessary, it was provided by two bilingual persons and later checked by observers, including two Costa Rican sociologists, also bilingual. Finally, the items were subjected to a brief pre-test in a student sample to determine clarity and discrimi- natory powers. The questionnaire was a closed response, paper and pencil instrument, and in general posed no problems to the students who are accustomed to mass testing procedures. The cooperation of the students and their instructors was exemplary. Administration to the final sample was conducted by the author with a Costa Rican assistant, or by one of us alone. Comparison of results of situations in which only one of us was present, indicates that no differences were observable which were related to my presence. We were assigned regular class hours to administer the questionnaire. Administration required about thirty minutes. A uniform introduction was read to each group before they began completing the questionnaire. The sample will be described in a later section in full, but it is totally comprised of high school seniors. CHAPTER I Part II The Association of Socio-Economic Development with the Growth of The Cultures of Modernity and Democracy Modern industrial societies rely upon mass mobilization for economic success. By contrast, traditional societies were based on the cultural parochialism and social isolation of the masses, and thus maintained socially static populations dominated by small, but politically and socially active and powerful elites. The plantation economies based on mono-cultural export or subsistence. agriculture 'which characterized much of traditional Latin America, made it possible for very small segments of society to consolidate economic and political control of the nations. One aspect of this pattern of power was the great social difference between classes which resulted from.the patterns of ownership and production. The latter required either large scale ownership or manual labor. Except insofar as the Church and the military provided such positions, relatively few persons who could be called "middle class” in status could exist in such a milieu. The glacial shift of investment, and therefore labor, from mono-culturally based export and subSistence agriculture and from mining, toward diversified forms of commerce, toward the fabrication for and sale in internal markets of industrial goods, toward services, and toward prior processing of raw materials to be exported, has 19 20 begun to change these patterns fundamentally in Latin America. Increasing economies of the area have attained a stage of transition in which agriculture remains dominant, but in.which its dominance is decreasing. (This is certainly the case in Costa Rica as will be demonstrated in the following chapter.) The result of such a process is not inevitably the demise of an economy dominated by traditional elites, in terms of ownership at least, as the Brazilian, Japanese, and even Costa Rican examples make clear.32 In those cases a common pattern has been the transfer of wealth garnered in traditional economies into modern industry with somewhat successful maintenance of many traditional social patterns of social status and deference. However, it is also quite clear that the growth of industry in the modern era means also the growth of what Johnson calls the "middle sectors."35 The middle sector is an amorphous population grouping consisting of both manual and non- manual elements with the common characteristic that they are not tied to the land and have some marketable skills.34 With the growth in numbers and prosperity of this group, and with the increasing depend- ence of modern owners on its managerial and productive skills, it has come, Johnson argues, to dominate the political realities of many Latin American nations still in transition to modernity. (That is not to say, of course, that this group is itself unified). Thus, even where millions remain unemployed, or are involved in traditional occupations, the structure of society is changing in basic ways. The rural, isolated, non-industrial, subservient life style is passing, and the modal social characteristics are becoming urban residence and dependence on the vicissitudes of an industrializing 21 economy heavily controlled by the actions of government (and foreign investors) rather than on the fortunes of an agricultural economy determined by deity, fate, or, more likely, the local "patron." Deutsch, in his seminal work on the dynamics of social mobiliza- tion and political development, makes the interaction between these processes of socio-economic development and cultural change a central theme.35 In that work, he argues that modernization may be considered the process of destruction of old cultural forms and their replacement by cultural attributes related to the social and technological processes characteristic of the industrial, mobilized society. To the extent that the traditional economic processes are maintained, traditional sets of opportunities for employment, social relations, and communications are all maintained. Economic deveIOpment, in short, not only affects the structure of socio-economic power by altering patterns of control, but also sets the parameters of opportunity in which new cultural norms are formed by socially active persons. In sum, the opportunities and socializing experiences which undergird a culture are themselves in a process of change during economic transformation. But what evidence of an empirical nature exists to support the assertions offered here? Fortunately, substantial evidence has been provided by a number of authors. Inkeles has demonstrated that as opposed to control groups who lacked such experience, factory workers, or persons involved in similar roles structured by the needs of a modern economy, increase substantially in the "modernity" of their attitudes in a given time 36 period. ‘Horeover, this finding is consistent among the six nations 22 he studied, indicating substantial cross cultural validity for the hypothesis. Lerner, in his classic, The Passinggof Traditional Society, demonstrates that "empathy" is related to several (independent) variables which represent aspects of socio—economic development, 37 such as media exposure, literacy and other variables. Empathy is a major factor involved in the development of a peculiarly modern set of perspectives on life, he finds, especially with regard to awareness of the world, including the political world, beyond the traditional village and family and one's potential to take part in it. Hie, Powell and Prewitt, in a recent reanalysis of the gizig_ Culture five nation data, have also demonstrated that persons they designate as being modern in social type (middle class and belonging to formal organizations) tend to be substantially more ”modern" in their behaviors and in many cases in their attitudes, than persons of other social characteristics.38 Thus insofar as socio-economic development implies the growth of the middle class and of the properb tion of persons who belong to various secondary groups, the culture will modernize as development procedes.39 Rogers has conducted a study similar in design to my own which has shown an association between economic development and cultural norms. Comparing several Colombian villages which vary substantially in scores of development measured with aggregate data, he finds that the respondents in each of the towns manifest distinctive patterns of attitudes, depending’on the level of development of the town in which they reside.40 He argues that the varied environments 23 provide differing experiences among the towns, particularly with respect to experiences with communications, and that such varied experiences lead to differing attitudes. There appears then, to be ample evidence that one can expect variance in a number of attitudinal dimensions related to political modernity in general, according to differences in level of socio- economic development. Socio-Economic Development as Associated With Democratic Forms of Modernity However, if the question of the develoPment of "modern” attitudes has received substantial attention from empirical researchers, the related question of the simultaneous development of a "culture of democracy" with economic development has received scant attention, though some work has been done which is indirectly related to the question and which will suggest the approach to be followed here. Lipset and Outright have both shown that some correspondence exists between levels of economic development and democratic institup tions, an association.which suggests a similar relationship of develop- ment to democratic cultures.41 The most thorough critic of their work has been Reubauer. He acknowledges that relatively democratic systems tend to be developed economically.42 However, this association is, he argues, only of the grossest sort. It appears to him to involve the creation of the basic infrastructure needed to provide for minimal levels of mass participation in politics, and for a mobilized papulation. In short, socio-economic development makes mass democracy possible in that it provides the facilities for it and the mobilised populations which may utilize it.43 By the same logic, however, its result is 24 not necessarily democratic, but simply modern. The direction a system.may take toward a totalitarian or democratic model of modernity, he argues, depends largely on elite choices. Referring to the leaders of the transitional systems, he points out that they ”are free to choose from a variety of alternatives, their form of organizations."44 Neubauer's own research shows that within a sample of democratic nations only, that differences in levels of development are not generally associated with "degrees of democratic performance."45 The only variable on which he obtains a significant correlation with democratic performance, is "communications;"46 In short, once it has decided upon a democratic form of politics, an elite will not automatically be able to expect that the nation will become more democratic with every subsequent increase in the level of development after the initial infrastructure of social communication and interaction has been laid. If Lipset's and Cutright's arguments had been correct, the level of development ought to have been associated with degrees of democracy as well as with gross differences in democracy and non-democracy. The fact that Reubauer has found that it is not generally so associated suggests a need to be quite cautious in constructing hypotheses relating development to democratic cultures in the present work. However, it does not indicate that such relationships are not to be expected. First, Heubauer does report a substantial relationship between communications facilities and democratic performance, as noted above. Thus to the extent that the index of internal developmental differences in use in the present study reflects the degree to which communication 25 occurs between the most developed and least developed areas of the country a relationship may be expected. Furthermore, Neubauer has dealt only with international variation among systems, not with intrapnational differentiation. Where the latter is the case, it seems to me, one may extend Reubauer's logic to suggest that elites will take advantage of improving communications facilities to extend the norms of democracy, which they have already effectively established in an institutional sense in central areas, to the less developed areas of the nation. The Costa Rican elite seems committed to this type of extension of democratic participation and belief. In 1953 universal suffrage was introduced. Since then a system of universal registration through the census bureau has been deve10ped. Programs to register persons in the rural areas for voting purposes and to make polling places accessible to them continue. Furthermore, the Supreme Tribunal of Elections conducts regular sessions in the roles of democratic 47 citizenship in the public schools. Moreover its support for the abstract idea of democracy was demonstrated in the civil war of 1948 and subsequent events, as noted earlier. At a later stage of analysis, then I shall hypothesize that given the apparent committment of elites to democratic styles of politics, that one may expect the developmental differences among the regions of Costa Rica to result in differing levels of support for the procedural norms of democracy simply because the ability of the elites to communicate such norms in the peripheral areas is relatively limited, and because traditional authoritarian norms which may militate against acceptance of such norms are likely to continue 2: to exist in these areas. (These hypotheses will be further specified and examined below in chapter four). The'Within~System Study of variation in Political Culture Although I am dealing in this study with only one nation, the literature which is concerned with the sorts of problems of interest to me here has most often been comparative between nations, not comparative between regions of a single nation. How well do the notions of mobilization and culture change lend themselves to the study of within nation differences? Linz, discussing regional differences in Spain, argues that many of the political and cultural differences in Spain can be accounted for by reference to theories such as mobilization- development theory, usually applied to intersystem comparison.48 Although the political, economic and cultural differences among regions of a single nation are likely to be less than differences among’nations, they may nevertheless be substantial, particularly when a nation is in a period of transition. Lerner has observed that nations may be characterized as divided between "center" and "periphery."l Center and periphery, according to his usage, are distinguished according to several criteria including extent of power and level of development. While the terms need not necessarily refer to geographic entities, one reference, and the one I shall employ here, is to regional differences in developmental levels. If one applies the center-periphery terminology to characterize the spread of socio-economic development, he makes the implicit 27 suggestion that development has an epicenter from which lines of influence flow or diffuse. This is an intuitively satisfying notion not only for understanding diffusion processes on a world scale, but also on an intra—national scale when development begins in a mono- centric way as it has in most areas of Latin America including Costa Rica. Within nation differences in transitional societies thus carry two implications (at least) for the researcher: They will often enable him to rank-order regions on a developmental continuum in order to test hypotheses utilizing "developmental level" as a continuous variable; They imply a dynamic situation in which peripheral areas are growing toward or changing in the direction of, the present state of the central areas. The comparison of center and periphery on the basis of relative levels of development, therefore, is theoretically similar to a comparison of a single region over time, and thus a source of prediction of the future conditions of the periphery, though not of the center, which lacks a "future" reference point. Although a host of exogenous variables ranging from.race-related sub-cultural differences to economic failures many render such predictions highly tenuous, some cautious speculations about the specific case may be made. An Alternative Perspective on the Relationship Between Development and Modern Democratic Culture Although it is an assumption made by most authors in the field of development related research, are we justified in assuming that the relationships between developmental factors and attitudes remain constant through space and time? Despite the fact that most authors 28 simply do not consider this issue, the assumption is likely to prove oversimplified at best. The process of development is nowhere very uniform, even within societies. With respect to processes of communications, for example, the reliance of recipients of messages on a mediating, interpreting authority to validate (or invalidate) media messages is likely to be greater in the more traditional areas of a nation where word of mouth communication and traditional authority figures continue to play a more central role in social life.49 Thus the impact of a given unit of media exposure in a traditional area is likely to be quite different than in a more modern area, though without a knowledge of the pre- conditions into which the communication was introduced, one could not predict the nature of the difference. Another example of the probability of differing consequences of the introduction of influences of the industrial society is provided by the variable, social status. His and his colleagues have argued that one factor in developmental change is the increase in sheer size of the middle class.50‘ The conclusion to be drawn from this is that as the number of persons holding'middle class characteristics increases with development, the culture of a political system "modernizes." Yet the increasing size of the middle class involves not only changes in sheer numbers, but also changes in the relationships among status groups. The nee-feudal patronal system which continues even in its decline to dominate subsistence and plantation agriculture in many parts of Latin.America, implies a relationship of control and subservience between higher and lower status groups. The growth of a middle class, however, suggests the passing of this relationship and the rise of a 29 greater equality of power potential between the status groups. The variable "social status" would thus become a less important source of differentiation among people as development progressed. Unionization movements and a trend toward dependence of industry on skilled labor might be expected to have similar effects. Frequently, then, in developmental research we may be dealing with time continua across which predictions from one social or psychological variable to another do not remain constant. When this is the case, then, we must conceive of regions or nations at varied levels of development as having not only differences in the proportions of given characteristics in their populations, but also differences in the impact that those characteristics may have. This view implies that societies at varied levels of develOpment must be seen as rather discrete units which are to be characterized not only in terms of their aggregate characteristics, but also in terms of the relationships among those characteristics. In the case of the study of within nation differences, these considerations may become even more complex because of the fact that the institutions of national government are likely to be reasonably uniform throughout a nation, at least legally. Yet the socialization processes underlying participation in those institutions may differ widely among areas which are very different in developmental level, despite the unifying effects of growing national governments. Thus the role of "participant" may be filled in different areas by persons of differing backgrounds and experiences. In short, despite differing attitudes, motivations, and social characteristics, the behaviors which appear to be consequent to those factors (e.8. voting) may be fairly 30 constant, for they are in fact structured by the institutions of a single national government. Finally, the factor of reaction to change may befoul the notion that the most educated and prestigious segments of society will also tend to be most receptive to new ideas. While that is a common prediction, the response of such groups to innovation in the political sphere depends in part on the degree to which the innovation is threaten- ing to the established position of such elite groups. Potentially this factor could have the effect of reversing the predictions offered by the lie hypothesis discussed earlier, in areas in which middle and upper status groups of society find change threatening, despite the fact that such persons may be most likely to be exposed to such ideas. To some extent, therefore, as societies modernize they become characterized by attitudes characteristic of modern cultures. However, that phenomenon may often be more a halting development of new systems of interaction among variables than a continuous and coinciding growth of economic and cultural modernity. The primary difficulty of introducing such a concept into the discussion of the relationship between develop- ment and political culture is that it makes prediction of the attitup dinal consequences of given levels of development virtually impossible, at least in the short run, for it suggests that regions at each level of development must be treated as separate entities. In sum, it suggests that developmental level is not a continuous variable at all, but rather a set of discrete categories with little in common. m In general, one may anticipate that with the development of an industrial economy will come also the growth of a culture of 31 modernity. Furthermore when elites are committed to the extension of democracy within their system, continued economic development will enhance their ability to spread the norms of democracy, for they will provide facilities for communication and interaction, and will tend to destroy the pro-existing tendencies toward authoritarian cultural patterns and social isolation. Within national systems, such variation may be evident among*regions which differ in levels of development. It must also be considered possible that the interbregional differences anticipated.will not appear but that the data will demonstrate that the developmentally different regions actually differ primarily in terms of the relationships among variables which occur within them. In such a case developmental level could not be said to be without effect. Yet neither would its impact on the bivariate relationship between development and attitudes which remains the core issue of this research, be predictable without a very detailed knowledge of local variations in society and culture. Thus where such differences are evident - and they in fact do become a fundamental theme -— an opportunity will be provided not only to reject the general hypothesis that with development increase both the modernity and democratic tendencies of a political culture, but also to attempt to develop alternative explanations of the rela- tionship between development and political culture. However, that task is best left to the stage of data analysis. The prior task is the demonstration of processes of, and regional differences in, development in the Costa.Rican setting. I shall turn to that task in the chapter which follows. CHAPTER I FOOTNOTES 1Karl Mannheim, Freedom, Power and Democratic Planning (New York: Oxford university Press, 1950), pp. 200-203 and 230-232. Harold Lasswell, The Political Writings of Harold Lasswell (New York: The Free Press, 1951), pp. 495-514. Lucian w. Pye, Politics, Personality and Nation Building (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1962), pp. 51—55. 2Mannheim, Freedom, Power and Democratic Planning, pp. 200-203. 3Pye, Politics,gPersonalitypand Nation Building, pp. 50-55. 4Lasswe11, Political Writings of Harold Lasswell, pp. 495-496. 5Alex Inkeles, "Participant Citizenship in Six Developing Countries," American Political Science Review,_December, 1969, p. 1123. 6Pye,nglitics. Personality and Nation Building, pp. 51-55. Pye, in fact, makes a similar argument. 7Mannheim, Freedom,gPower and Democratic Planning, pp. 200-205 and 250-232. Also Inkeles discusses this point at length in: Inkeles, ”Participant Citizenship in Six Developing Countries,” pp. 1121-1123. 8Berelson, Bernard, et a1., VOting (Chicago: university of Chicago Press, 1954), pp. 305-326. 9Charles F. Denton, Patterns of Costa Rican Politics (Boston: Allyn-Bacon, 1971), p. a. 10Angus Campbel et a1., The American'Voter, (Abridged ed.; New ‘York: 'Wiley, 1964), p. 58. 11V. 0. Key, Public Opinion and American Democracy (New York: Alfred Knopf, 19657:fpp. 182-206. 128cc for example the use of attitudes as intervening variable between developmental factors and political participation in five cultures in: Norman H. Nie et a1., "Social Structure and Political Participation: Developmental Relationships, Part I," American Political Science Review, June 1969, pp. 561-378, especially p. 565. 1156: iNorman‘H:iNie et a1., "Social Structure and Political Parti- cipation: Developmental Relationships, Part II," American Political Science Review, September, 1969, pp. 808-832, especially p. 811. 32 35 13Gabriel Almond and Sydney verbs, The Civic Culture (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963). 14Almond and verba studied samples from the united Kingdom, the United States, Germany, Italy and Hexico. They did not, for example, consider the possibility that a unique set of cultural attributes different from the civic culture may be required for the stable, successful functioning in a culture which in the pre-modern era was highly authoritarian, or in which present elites are committed for nonpcultural reasons to the establishment of institutions of collective decision making which are not of the legislative nature their political competence scale seems to assume. lsflarry Eckstein, Division and Cohesion in Democracy (Princeton: Princeton university Press, 1966). Crane Brinton, The Anatomy of Revolution (New York: Vintage Books, 1957). especially pp. 53-54. Mannheim, Freedom, Power and Democratic Planning. Lasswell, Thg_ Political writings of Harold Lasswell. 16Daniel Goldrich, Sons of the Establishment (Chicago: Rand Nblally, 1966). 17Paul R. Abramson and Ronald Inglehart, ”The Development of Systemic Support in Four Western Democracies,” Comparative Political Studies, January, 1970, pp. 405-418. 18 Goldrich, Sons of the Establishment, pp. 1-6. 19Donald H. Levine, "Ethiopia, Identity, Authority and Realism," in Lucian Pye and Sydney verbs, eds., Political Culture and Political Development.(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965), pp. 247- 249. 20Pye, Politics, Personality and Nation Building, particularly part‘v, pp. 211-284. 21This concept is derived from the work of Almond and Verbs on ”citizen competence' among adults. See Almond and verba, The Civic Culture, pp. 214-229. The items as adapted from their work appear in full here in Appendix A, listed under "Pre-Citizen Competence," Pm 1‘0 22 See Appendix A, Part 2.c. 23See Appendix A for a list of all items used to construct these indices and scales. The reader will note that this list is composed of themes developed by other authors. It is heavily dependent on the following: Inkeles, "Participant Citizenship in Six Developing Countries,”: Almond and verbs, The Civic Culture: Goldrich, Sons of the Establishment. 24Almond and verbs, The Civic Culture, p. 231, footnote no. 1. 34 25Robert N. Ford, "A Rapid Scoring Procedure for Scaling Attitude Questions," Public Opinion Quarterly, Fall, 1950, pp. 507-532. 26A striking example of the significance of this attitudinal variable in developmental research is given in: Norman R. Nie et a1., "Social Structure and Political Participation: Developmental Relation- ships, I," American Political Science Review, June, 1969, p. 811. 27Angus Campbell, et a1., The American Voter (New York: John Wiley, 1960), p. 517. 28The items used are similar to those used by the Survey Research Center in 1956 and 1960. See John P. Robinson and Phillip R. Shaver, Measures of Social P chological Attitudes (Ann Arbor, Institute for Survey Research, 1969 . Originally they were adapted for the Costa Rican student study from: F. Barron, "An Ego Strength Scale Which Predicts Response to Psychotherapy," pp. 226-234; George S. Welsh and W. Grant Dahlstrom, eds., Basic Reading on the MMPI in Psychology and Medicine. 29Pye, Politics, Personality and Nation Building, pp. 125-51-55. 5OGoldrich, Sons of the Establishment, p. 10. slIbid, pp. 104-125. Also: Almond and verbs, The Civic Culture, pp. 526-549. éZSamuel Z. Stone, Los Cafepgleros: Une Etude des Planteurs / de Cafe au Costa Rica. These de Doctorat du Troisieme Cycle Presents devant la Faculté des Lettres et Sciences Humaines. Université de Paris, 1968, especially p. 142. Seymour M. Lipset, "Values, Education and Entrepreneurship," in Seymour M. Lipset and Also Solari, eds., Elites in Latin America, (new York: Oxford University Press, 1967), pp. 13-14. Robert E. Ward, "Japan: The Continuity of Medernization," in Pye and Verba, eds., Political Culture and Political Development, DP. 27‘820 33John Johnson, Political Change in Latin America, (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1958), pp. 1-14. 34Ibid. 35Karl‘w. Deutsch, "Social Mobilization and Political Development," American Political Science Review, September, 1961, pp. 493-514. 36Inkeles, "Participant Citizenship in Six Developing Countries," pp. 1130-1138 and 1141. 37Daniel Lerner, The Passing of Traditional Society (new York: The Free Press, 1964). 38Nie et a1., ”Social Structure and Political Participation, Developmental Relationships, Part I.," pp. 366-378, 35 39Ibid. 4OEverett'M. Rogers et a1., Duffusion of Innovation Research Department, No. 2, "Opinion Leadership in Traditional and Modern Colombian Communities," (October 1964), mimeo, Department of Com- munications, Michigan State University. 41Seymour'M. Lipset, "Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy," in Charles F. Cnudde and Deane E. Neubauer, eds., Empirical Democratic Theory(Chicago: Markham, 1969), pp. 151-192. Phillips Outright, "National Political Development: Measurement and Analysis," in Ibid., pp. 193-209. 42Deane E. Neubauer, "Some Conditions of Democracy," in Ibid., pp. 224-235. Neubauer points out that although Outright does not explicitly state that his work is a study of democracy, his measures of "development" amount to an operational definition of development as democratic development. 43;y;g,, p. 232. 44;p;g., p. 233. 45lpig., pp. 229-230. 452239,, p. 231. 47Interview with Sr. Rafael Villegas Antillon, attorney and "vigilador" for the Supreme Tribunal of Elections, August 18, 1968. 48Juan J. Linz and Amando de Miguel, "Within Nation Differences and Comparisons: The Eight Spains," in Richard Merritt and Stein Rokkan, eds., Comparing_Nations (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966), pp. 267-320, see especially p. 280. 49Daniel Lerner, "Some Comments on Center-Periphery Relations," in Merritt and Rokkan, ComparingLNations, pp. 259-266. 50Ithiel de Sola Pool, "The Mass Media in the Modernization Process," in Lucian Pye, eds., Communications and Political Development, PP. 234-253e 51Nie et a1., "Social Structure and Political Participation, Developmental Relationships, Part I." CHAPTER II COSTA RICA: TRANSITIONAL DEMOCRACY AND RESEARCH SITE According to the theoretical position adopted in Chapter I, economic development tends to be associated with the spread of the culture of modern democracy where elites are committed to that direction of modernizing processes, and where democracy is not grossly incongruent with pro-existing cultural norms. This position raises several questions which have only been touched upon to this point and which require further examination for the reader unfamiliar with Costa Rica, especially. Can we assume that Costa Rican elites are committed to the maintenance of democratic political processes? Does the economic system contain sufficient internal variation in levels of deve10pment to be utilized as an independent variable? And given the need to utilize limited resources carefully, what type of sample will be used and what relationship does it bear to the processes of development and the operations present and future of the political system? This chapter is an attempt to answer these questions. Costa Rica violates many of the adages concerning the development of stable democracy and many of the truisms concerning the nature of politics in Latin America. It is a small underdeveloped country of Latin culture. Its society is undergoing substantial changes involving 36 37 industrialization, restructuring of its social stratification system, and very rapid population growth (82% growth since 1950). Yet the gradual development of stable democracy has been seriously inter- rupted only once during the past twenty years. That single major disruption was a civil war touched off by a succession crisis and involved the re-establishment of orderly, relatively democratic electoral procedures. This relative stability and the normal exchange of political power among the parties during elections sets Costa Rica apart from most other Central and South America which face frequent succession crises in which elections are marked by great disorder, or in which elections are squelched by elites in power. On the other hand, Costa Rica is not without many of the usual characteristics of Latin American politics such as a high degree of personalism in her political parties, and the preeminence of a few select families in politics. Yet, Costa Rica has a relatively highly "developed" political system, in the sense that despite these aspects of her political life, and despite the rapid socio-economic change she is undergoing, she has a fairly stable party structure, an orderly electoral process marked by wide- spread popular participation and regular, rather fair elections generally accepted as legitimate. It is thus a deviant case relative to many other systems of Central and South America and to theories which relate political stability and development to high levels of socio—economic development. Physically, Costa Rica is small, about the size of west Virginia. In 1965 the population stood at 1,459,000.1 Nearly 60% of that population is of less than twenty years of age, a fact which indicates that among the primary problems of the government during the 1970's will be the promotion of employment through III II I l I II All 1' I I.|| .III I: 1| i 38 a, _; sodomy "71 ' an arm E ”A” "mag. “ coprocq/ \‘ . . ‘s \'. pro/n: JOCI4N fiddp/(J from flI/a: [.3 fad/silks dc Cos/a Pita, 1.953 Fig”. 2e1 Political and Physical Map of Costa Rica 39 industrialization, restructuring of its social stratification system, and very rapid population growth (82% growth since 1950). Yet the gradual development of stable democracy has been seriously intrrupted only once during the past twenty years. That single major dusruption.was a civil war touched off by a succession crisis and involved the re- establishment of orderly, relatively democratic electoral procedures. This relative stability and the normal exchange of political power among the parties during elections sets Costa Rica apart from most other Central and South America which face frequent succession crises in which elections are marked by great disorder, or in which elections are squelched by elites in power. On the other hand, Costa Rica is not without many of the usual characteristics of Latin American politics such as a high degree of per- sonalism in her political parties, and the preeminence of a few select families in politics. Yet, Costa Rica has a relatively highly "developed" political system in the sense that despite these aspects of her political life, and despite the rapid socio-economic change she is undergoing, she has a fairly stable party structure, an orderly electoral process marked by widespread popular participation and regular, rather fair elections generally accepted as legitimate. It is thus a deviant case relative to many other systems of Central and South America and to theories which relate political stability and development to high levels of socio- economic development. Physically, Costa Rica is small, about the size of West Virginia. In 1965 the population stood at 1,459,000.1 Nearly 60% of that population is of less than twenty years of age, a fact which indicates that among the primary problems of the government during the 1970's will be the promotion of employment through 40 further and faster industrial expansion, and provision of a rapid expansion of the system of national education to maintain Costa Rica's high standards of education and to serve the need of new industry for skilled personnel. About 53% of the total population reside in the central plateau which is commonly called the meseta central by the natives and most authors. The 922232, though it is the center of the nation's life and contains the bulk of the population, contains only four or five per cent of the nation's land area. The metropolitan area of the capital, San Jose, which lies in the m, has a population of about 325,000 and dominates the life of the mgsgt§_much as the latter dominates the life of the nation as a whole. The next largest city, Alajuela, also located in the E£§232.3r°3 has 20,000 inhabitants, a fact which gives some indication of the totality of the dominance of San Jose. Already San José has 7r% of the urban population and is growing faster than the other areas. Thus it is likely that its disproportionate size will be accentuated in the future. This problem is familiar throughout Latin America as the capital cities or ports industrialize and grow with migration from the interior, and is not unique to Costa Rica. Culturally the nation is characterized by a certain moderation. One who deals with Latin American politics becomes accustomed to numerous examples of societal breakdown in which the stresses of social change apparently overwhelm the capacity of traditional institutions to cope with them. The Colombian "boggtozo" and the subsequent La Violencia come quickly to mind. Coups and riots in Panama, peasant leagues in Brazil, Tupemaro terror in Uruguay, the 41 very widespread culture of poverty all bear witness to the existence of widespread breakdown of traditional political and social structures and norms. Costa Rica has experienced a major Civil war, a minor invasion, a number of riots and political strikes of a relatively minor nature since the late 1940's. However, there are few signs of the massive social breakdown which is indicated by the violence and anomic movements which have come to be expected of other nations of the Southern American continent. In this sense, then, the society appears to be adapting’reasonably well to the stresses of change from a rural peasant economy to an urban industrial economy. Economically, Costa Rica continues to have limited, yet in some senses substantial success with development. The gross domestic product per capita was 8451 in 1964 and higher than most in Latin America.2 The aowth rate has been 6.4% annually. But when the effects of inflation and particularly of population growth are deducted, the rate falls to O.T% per capita - very little in terms of increasing satisfaction of individuals.3 On the other hand, increased employment opportunities depend not on per capita figures but of total increase in production, and in this Costa Rica's economy seems to have kept pace, though recent figures are not available. At least this seems to be true of expansion of employment opportunities for persons of some education such as those studied here. Danton reports that virtually all high school graduates, even those who fail in the examination for the bachillerato can expect to find satisfactory employment.4 Unless the economy of the United States recovers its strength soon, the Costa Rican economy may suffer a severe setback for it depends upon the United States as an export 42 market. Again, however, the long range projection would appear to be a growth rate which just keeps pace with population growth. Although the economy is not forging ahead rapidly in terms of growth, of equal importance to the present research is its gradual change in composition. The manufacturing sector is growing most rapidly, followed by governmental and service sectors of the economy. While agricultural production has increased and coffee and banana exports have remained important sources of employment and foreign exchange the total percentage contribution of the agricultural sector to the gross national product has declined from 44.8% in 1950 to 31.7% in 1964.5 Thus, despite theslow per-capita growth rate, the econow is undergoing fundamental change. 6 Further evidence of the fundamental change in the economy is found in relative growth statistics. In the period 1962-1964 manufacturing grew at a rate of 10% per annum while agricultural output increased at only 5.27%.7 On the other hand, as was pointed out above, this does not yet mean that agriculture has lost its dominant position. By 1964, industry accounted for 15% of the GNP, while agriculture accounted for 31%. (The public sector and "other," primarily services, comprised the remaining 54%). Also, of the export sector, coffee, bananas, and cacao accounted together for 74% of total earnings. This figure is indicative of the nation's continued dependence on an essentially mono-cultural export econonw, a dependence which creates difficulties due to the falling world price for coffee and the obvious need for foreign exchange to maintain the pace of industrialization, and to maintain necessary imports of foods and other commodities.8 43 For the moment, however, the transitional process is continuing, and one quickly becomes accustomed to the typical anomalies of the transitional areas such as delivery of goods to rail and air freight services by horsedrawn vehicles, peasants listening to transistor radios (frequently in nu experience to broadcasts of the debates of the lational Assembly, though I may have been acquainted with unusual persons of peasant stock). But all of the sights which at first startle the visitor forcefully indicate a fundamental technological and social transformation of a people. As is true elsewhere in Latin America, the contrast between the scenery of the national center, San Jose and the 93332 in general, and the periphery is sharp. To those who have traveled through both areas it will seem superfluous, even pedantic, to demonstrate the contrasts with demographic data. That which appears to the traveller as a contrast in climate, standard of living, racial type, life style, between dependence on the horse and the use of trucks, buses and automobiles, between a cosmopolitan urban center and tiny rural towns, appears in the statistical abstracts as differing occupational types, infant mortality rates, consumption of electric power, and other variables. Careful study of Table 2.1 indicates that in most cases the provinces of Guanacaste, Puntarenas, and Limén, are consistently rather low in rank if one rank orders the scores, with Alajuela joining them in some cases because of its large rural population in the northeast. In literacy and infant mortality the rates are rather uniform, however, a commentary on the substantial success of the national systems of hospital care and education in equalizing 44 Huge n... ugomsevzoxmopnnpoo— arousnnennunnnu on noun.— ”has: Science m r e 1 A e e e 8 n . en 6 n p... p a n m m m we a n a .e. y .e 0 vs a 3 0 :6 p) t t em as D. 8 1 r t 89 C n 8 e M 1 t 8 \l 0 e e e e O m Me” a” m a r b“. m a“ r a m u u u e t t t c ”we. L. i e e l n tM t 7 C n n n c m m m f Po. m( ». PM a i u e u am Is! as t t m t 3 c a... 0 fuel. .1 C S 3 t 3 m V n.(\ n n" n o n r m n n .. nnu _u.u r .m m .m.m eeuu .m . . e e e t e n e e s .w em. 1 t e c c n e an m m mm me me an m mm mm w an an am e .a n. .t s. “r e .r m .r w .m u :. .m.s .r u mm “umw .5 n .muw .m mulljaldfllllafllll as: norm are an we so up u» on no em uuo co um om.ra pm we range—ops N: am, 5 5 up 5 u» 5 mu 2 8 5 5b 5 mm cannons 30 5 u "N 5 5 v m we no M» Na. a.» no mu monomum mo a u u a a m a mu no um um a.q we on acumencmno umu um - m p» u a c on a u m u.— —a mo assessors. son an Ne so so u o e on no as m u.» so no swam: mm u an a u N a u «0 pa N— m ~.o up a» ~>chz>r sonar s.eue pee poo poo see see pee on on ”no no we see.es .o emu :ono" museum cm .693 «an woman—songs an macs are 95055 mosses” resend m. revenge. wanna gunman sea 53325 he ran»: Ensues. 65080" zen—Gas. ~33 v. So :2- EHonnnms assess: an muncfimnuoo a 02.50 a. HHH oonmo no Haacmnnncm vncssmsoncnensu. 52.. v. 80. «sews ww. smsvnem 6% season. as Sumner“: mesons: no wancamnuno v. oesuo a. 2.3930 mansaurnuoo as nouns ”was. 53. m. n5. new—o 3». sea Hose. noose sou. 45 opportunities. The major exception to this uniformity is the very high rate of infant mortality which occurs in Lim6n only. This tragically high rate in a relative sense, indicates the isolation of the people of Lim6n, and gives one pause, for Lim6n is the only area of the nation with a virtually completely black population. Linén lies on the Atlantic coast, serving as the Atlantic port. Its population is primarily composed of imigrants from the West Indies. The local language is a peculiar mix of English and Spanish. Many of the residents are bilingual. If this is an advantage occasionally to residents who migrate to San Jose, it nevertheless accentuates the racial differences between the residents of Lim6n and the population of the 22223.“. which is almost entirely European in origin. Geographically too, Limon is isolated. Though the capital city of the province (also called Lim6n) is the nation's only eastern port, it is tied to the remainder of the nation only by an ancient rail line and by air routes. No highway which would provide more rapid and cheaper transport has yet been constructed, though perpetual planning continues. A widespread comment of citizens of Limon reported during a labor riot in Lim6n was that "We are a separate country.” While that claim is an exaggeration, particularly for a people which comprises only five percent of Costa Rica's small population, Limo/n certainly does remain effectively isolated from the mainstream of Costa Rican life. Economically too, it is of the periphery. Deserted by the United Fruit Company in the 1930's because of the ”Panasa Disease” (which attacked the non-resistant strains of bananas grown there), the area outside the port city is now one of subsistence farming 9 and some production of cacao for export. Recently banana cultivation has been reintroduced, but it has not regained its former scale. With Limén, Puntarenas shares a coastal, tropical location. Hewever, it is located on the Pacific coast. Its capital, also called Puntarenas, is the nation's only Pacific port. Culturally, Puntarenas is somewhat more integrated into the national mainstream being tied to the meseta central by rail, road and air. This is especially true of the port city, and much less so of the rural areas of the southwestern part of the province. Economically the province is characterized not only by the activities of the port city, but also by the ”factory farms” on.which two United States firms produce bananas for the world market. This has given rise to a tendency for workers there to be wage earners rather than persons tied strongly to the land, though subSistence agriculture is also verywidespread.10 Politically, this has led to the organizability of many workers into labor organizations and to a certain political radicalism in some parts of the province. Guanecaste, the province which occupies the northwest sector of the nation, is the only predominantly mestizo area of the country. As is often the case, the superficial racial difference indicates a cultural difference. The area is, according to informants from San José, more similar in culture to Nicaragua than to the EEEEEE; central in that it is an Indo-Spanish mix. Economically the province is rather underdeveloped. Agriculture is based on an hacienda system which profits the elite, and on subsistence farming which sustains the laborer and small-holder.11 Except for the elite few who have access to motorized transportation, 47 transportation is primarily by foot, horse, or ex cart. Similarly, farming is usually performed by traditional means of man and animal power rather than by mechanization. The remainder of the nation tends to be more developed economically, however it too shares the common characteristic of the other provinces, that the capital cities of the province are substantially more prosperous and developed than the outlying areas. The provinces of Cartago, Heredia, and Alajuela are particularly subject to this contrast. Their capital cities lie in the meseta central while their rural areas extend down from the plateau to the tropical lowlands and are quite underdeveloped. Thus the differences between more and less developed areas which characterize the nation as a whole, also characterize the individual provinces. A final word is in order concerning the racial differences among the regions. Despite the fact that some racial differences do exist, Costa Rica has not been cursed by the extreme racial division of labor which has characterized many nations of South America since colonial times. In most Latin American nations as in the United States, Indian or Negro slaves, indentured laborers, or serfs were used for labor and were brutalized physically and culturally. By contrast in Costa Rica the land was not sufficiently rich to make the importation of slave labor profitable. The Indians who occupied the territory at the time of white exploration and colonization were not amenable to servitude and either resisted white power or fled. Today only about I% of the population is Indian, though a substantial portion is mestizo (Indian-Caucasian), a fact which suggests that the original settlers were perhaps guilty of genocide or at least 48 substantial forced migration, but which also means that the political system does not face the enormous difficulty of integrating a large indigenous and culturally abused and fragmented people which is faced in most other nations of the Western HemiSphere.12 These are the main differences among the provinces of Costa Rica. They are discussed here to acquaint the reader with the full range of variation in a little known and small nation. The differences in developmental levels are substantial. However, it would be unrealistic to expect to find the sort of extreme cultural gaps between the most and least modern sectors of society which one would expect in, for example, Brazil or Peru. Rather one must expect to find more mdld differences. Furthermore, the sample utilized in this study (which will be described in full later in this chapter) minimizes the variation in two ways. It is a student sample, and the students are drawn from the capital "cities" of each province rather than from the provinces as a whole. Thus the variation by status and the ruralness of residence which exists in the total population, is not fully reflected in the sample. One might expect, in fact to find few substantial differences among the provincial capitals which would be related to levels of development and thus to cultural variables. Yet even with the relative homogeneity of the sample, differences remain. Transportation facilities, broadcasting facilities, proximity to national political events and personnel, differences in the quality of education and the urbanity of the teaching staffs, the extent of manufacturing, the marketing practices, the bureaucraticization of economic and political life all differ quite markedly among the 49 cities and can be expected to have some socializing impact upon even a sample of equal education levels. At present one cannot travel from the metropolitan area of San Jose to the towns of the periphery and expect to find cultural homogeneity, though as deve10pment procedes, ultimate near homogeneity is likely. Thus the study is not one of within nation differences in culture of the total population, but only of that part of the popula- tion - the relatively well-educated and urban - most likely to become politically active adults, and to pursue occupations which are of a responsible nature and in themselves relate to the operation of governmental and business activities. It is likely that this articulate minority (4% at 5% of the population have completed high school) will substantially dominate political initiatives for the forseeable future.13 Thus the residual impact of regional differences in dimensions of economic development may give some indication of the difficulties faced in the political integration of elite and near elite populations whose environments have differed substantially during childhood and adolescence. At the same time these differences may lead to further understanding of the relationship between the spreading processes of socio-economio development and the culture of modern democracy. §ggplingyProcedure For the purpose of studying attitudinal variation within the so called "prestige class” (middle and upper middle class) along lines of economic development, a sample was selected according to 14 the following criteria. Each province was included in order to 50 provide the widest variation possible in a relatively urban sample. Each school selected was to be the ”best" public, nondvocational high school of the provincial capital in which it was located. Except in San Jose these schools represent the source of the highest quality education available locally. (In San Jose there are also rather small private schools attended by the sons of the very upperb most elite; they are not included in the sample used here, but will be discussed in a separate study now under way.) In all of the provinces except San Jose, the "best public school" is coeducational. In San Jose, segregation by sex is still maintained. For this reason both the school for males and that for females were included in the San José sample, giving a total of eight schools from the seven provincial capitals. The choice of schools was not a problem except in San Jose, for there is only one public, nonwvocational high school in each of the capitals. In San Jose, the judgement of informants was used. Informants included the Director of the Department of the Social Sciences of the university of Costa Rica and the'Vice Minister of Education of Costa'Rica, and were verified by other less expert informants.15 In cases in which it was not possible to administer the questionnaire to all members of the senior class - only members of this class were utilised - classrooms were selected at random. Because the assignment of students to classrooms is alphabetic rather than systematic in any way, the samples can be considered random for the students of the fifth year ("senior class”) of each school. 51 The Capital Cities and variation in Economic Development In most transitional systems the focus of change, the vanguard of industrialisation, is localized in one or two major cities. In Costa Rica, San Jose is the unchallenged center of modernity.16 Innovation flows from San Jose to the periphery. Investment decisions of business and government are made in San Jose. Broadcasting facilities, the only university, the railroads, the bureaucracies of business and government are all headquartered or completely located in San Jose. Nor do there exist other cities which serve as specific centers of activity for certain types of enterprise, except Alajeula, which contributes land and labor to the international airport which serves the San Jose area, and a Firestone plant which is a major factory employing persons of both Alajeula and San Jose. (The two cities are also connected by the only superbhighway). From their headquarters in and near San Jose, banks, factories, and commercial enterprises slowly expand their operations outward. They do so timidly, cognizant of rural poverty, lack of mass markets in close proximity, and mass trained labor pools. Often the dis- advantages of location outside San Jose, force expansion of operations within the city itself. Related to this tendency is a migratory flow which steadily increases the size of San JosE. However, it is also true that commercial enterprise is moving outward, diffusing the process of economic development to the peripheral areas. In short, development has a uni-centric focus in San José, but it is slowly moving outward. Despite the obvious first rank of San José in the level of economic development, it was rather difficult to construct an index by which to place all of the capitals on a dimension of general, non 52 political development. Many statistics which are usually used for such an index were simply unavailable. For example, neither income per capita, nor the figures on which that summary statistic is based, are available distributed by capitals. ‘Moreover, the summary statistics which are available do not necessarily reflect developmental levels. For example, per capita income can be estimated from value- of-production data. Bewever, value of production includes profits and taxes as well as wages, and the former are very unlikely to be left or reinvested in the peripheral areas. Rather those funds, especially profits, will be exported (in the case of the United Fruit Company) or reinvested in San Jose. Only where such funds are actually invested in the area, will there be a substantial develop- mental effect. Thus I have used, rather than income figures or earnings figures, the value per capita of capital equipment in each city, as the first of three indicators. Other likely indicators which had to be rejected for various reasons were literacy rates (equalized in large part by national education) infant mortality rates (discussed previously), and percentage of pggggg_in the population. The latter seemed an especially useful bit of data, but had to be set aside, for it presented a totally unrealistic picture. The data may be faulty for it suggests that the larger the city the larger the proportion of 252225 (peasants) in the population. This suggests either that the pgggg§_listed are mdgrants no longer employed in agriculture, but not yet reemployed or that the process of data gathering on the elusive, frequently illiterate peasant is more effective in the relatively urban areas. Whatever the cause of the relationship, the cause of empirical 53 research would not be served well by its inclusion. With little recourse to other measures, then the following three items were utilized: (1) per capita value of capital equipment (buildings, machines, and vehicles in each provincial capital). (2) the absolute number of firms in each capital with an annual production of 750,000 colones per year, in 1954. (3) the absolute distance in kilometers from the national Center (determined by highest score on first two dimensions). The second and third dimensions add to the first two slightly different elements. The number of firms with a production as large as 750,000 colones gives a strong indication of the degree of urbani- sation. In the towns of the rural areas, one quickly observes that a substantial number of persons who are essentially rural laborers, make their homes in the towns. Thus, to rank the towns in terms of size of population gives only a measure of size, and not of the usual connotations of ”urbanization" which include the extent of production. One witty critic has suggested that this statistic be known as the "hustle-bustle” index; a realistic assessment of its nature. Finally, distance from the highest scorer on the first two variables, which, of course, is San Jose. While distance is not the best measure of the ease of diffusion of innovation from center to periphery, it is a useful one in this case. This bit of data is intended to express the relative isolation of the several towns or cities from the processes of economic development. Perhaps the best measures of such isolation would include measures of numbers 54 of communications of various sorts (data not available by town), or ease of transportation (not quantifiable). However, if one examines the simple distance statistic in the case of Costa Rica and compares it to impressions of the ease of transportation, he will find a close correspondence. For example it is thus useful in ranking the towns of the ggggtg_other than San Jose. Cartago, which on the other indicators falls far behind Alajuela, is benefited by the cheap and rapid bus service from San Jose which makes substantial economic intercourse possible. Moreover, it emphasizes again the isolation of Lhmén, which not only is geographically distant, but also very much isolated in terms of available transportation. One final comment is in order regarding the methodology of index construction. It was desired to have more than one town in each level of the index in order to partially correct by averaging any distortion that might be introduced into the data because of non- developmental factors covariant with the index. Therefore, designation of groupings was necessary. In order to maintain the a priori criterion of two (minimum) towns per set a three place index had to be used. Standard deviations were calculated for each of the towns on each of the index items. The standard deviations were averaged. The resulting averages, raw scores and groupings are as listed in Table 2.2. The reader will note that the variable is titled, "Centeereriphery," after the notions of intra-netional differences discussed by Lerner and Linz.17 Grouping was facilitated by the rather large differences among the three sets as listed in Table 2.2. The placement of only one town was questionable. Puntarenas, in terms of its score's 55 Table 2.2 ’ Rank order average standard deviation from mean and trichotomous grouping of the seven provincial capitals on selected indices of socio-economic development. *5 Capitals, rank Distance from Value per- Number of Standard ordered and financial and capita of firms pro- deviations grouped in communications capital ducing goods from mean final form center (San equipment or services scores derived from Jose) in miles. in dollars. with value averaged data at right.* greater than across the 894.000 in three pre- 1964. H ceding indices. Center: an Jos‘ 0 112.5 144 3.70 Llajuala 14 113.0 55 3.44 Mid Range: media 6 100.0 ' 11 1.81 Outage 14 105.5 14 1.80 Puntnenas V 72 72.5 11 -1.24 Periphery: , Linda 103 39.0 9 - 4.65 Liberia 130 33.0 1 - 5.41 * For purposes of comlational analysis which follows, the groupings were assigned scores. The Center was assigned a score of 3, the mid-range, 2, and the periphery, 1. *" In colones (local currency) 750,000. The figure is used by the Costa Rican Bureau of statistics to designate the lower bound of the second largest category of producers. The next category is 1 million and above. Both are included here. see All intonation drawn from: Censo de Industrial y Manufacturer-as, 19643 and Anuario Estadistica de Costa Rica, 1966, and adapted by author. 56 proximity to other scores, clearly belongs with the center grouping, since the criterion of assignment was the placement of each town with the closest score. Yet it falls below the mean with Liberia (capital of Guanecaste) and Lim6n. It was simply decided to adhere to the original rule of assignment rather than be concerned with deviation from the mean score. Since Puntarenas lies outside the geggtg, and is generally considered by analysts of Costa Rican society to be part of the low lying periphery, this assignment may be criticized. Hewever, not only is it consistent with the original index criteria, but Puntarenas itself occupies a position on lines of transportation and social interaction (it is a resort for San Jose) which distinguishes it from Liberia or Lim5n quite clearly to the traveler or merchant. The resulting sets are assigned rank scores, the Center receiving the highest score, 3, and the periphery the lowest, 1. The ranks are utilized later in correlational analysis which follows. Center and Periphery: Explaining Ecological Correlation with Individual Variables In Chapter I it was pointed out that although this would be primarily a study of cultural differences related to environmental differences among the regions, that it would also deal with the problem of explaining the expected differences in terms of variables which have a direct and measurable association with individual cases. In part by arbitrary decision, in part by reference to existing literature on development, the variables to be considered were limited to three: Social status, traditionalism and the process of participation in family decision making as a development-related socialization factor. For the moment I shall simply examine their 57 relationship to the independent variable, development, as measured by the Centeereriphery index. germ; It has become part of the historical commonplace spoken about the industrial revolution to refer to the growth of the middle class in the United Kingdom, France and the United States. Certain authors have capitalized on this idea, applying it to the process of political development in the Latin Americas and elsewhere. Johnson has argued convincingly that with the growth of the middle ”sectors" as he calls them, the style and substance of Latin American politics has undergone profound change in the direction of increased popular parti- cipation in politics, though not necessarily always more "democracy."18 Nie and his colleagues have shown that with middle and upper class status are associated the attitudinal norms of modern political 19 systems. The question for the present research, then, is the extent to which the factor status varies with development in the Costa Rican setting and with the index of development being utilized. Table 2.3 shows the relationship to be mild, though positive. As is true of many of the relationships to be observed throughout this data, the variation is not smoothly continuous from center to periphery, but appears primarily between the center and the remainder of the nation. At a later point of the analysis this observation will prove useful, for it will be necessary to dichotomize the regional dimension in order to preserve large enough sub-grouped samples for observation. Occupation of respondents' fathers proved to be the only indicator of social status available. Income and styles of consumption, 58 96.5.0 Pm oodaoflluonueoouw women as 38.8. swag. nosaou zualwooma nonporouw moouwH easement doves. em 33 3X A»; HR“ 3,; ES: mire: 8a :3 as $8 Hos... 3a 83 mom 903 3a 38 «sausage looaamot loom A33 38“ G: 23: 8a 33 we 33 5a :3 soapy new 43 84 * seven. I 9503 on panama 3.33.33. 0:53. dungeo- oH pagan—35.6.9. 358.0 I euowoomposbp. Houseman". (Ewe con—Hen. Hates. I 930w snowshoe..- o». EH. one on. «to Bob engages: 303.5th ohm c.3509 use sun—350m. Henson. snows 8.5 usurp. 59 two potential suupplementary factors, proved in pre-testing to be too sensitive socially to use with the expectation of cooperation of the students. Moreover, objection to such questions was voiced by two school administrators. Hewever, that occupation alone serves as an adequate indicator for the general purposes intended here seems beyond a reasonable doubt. The sample, the reader should recall, consists only of persons who are in the final year of high school. Thus they are likely to be far more homogeneous socially than the remainder of the population. Despite that, a substantial degree of variation appears in the sample. This variation is a commentary on the relatively wide availability of education in Costa Rica.20Whatever the social significance of the status variance, it is clear that sufficient numbers of persons of each social status group are included to make it possible to test the relationships in which status is thought to be important. Finally note also that the middle class of the San José- Alajuela area is substantially larger than that of the non~Central areas. Also notice that the non-Central areas contain not only larger classes of "lower" status, but also somewhat larger groups of persons of high - ownership - status. This relationship suggests that in the less developed areas there continues to exist, even among such a homogeneous population group as this one, the remnants of the rural agrarian bi-class system. This observation, as it happens, is perhaps the most important single fact concerning this data. The reasons for this will become clear in subsequent analysis. (0 These tendencies are also visible in the population over time, suggesting that the interbregional variation observed in this study presents a reasonable approximation of an over-time comparison. Table 2.4 shows the striking movement of the respondents' parents, grandparents and of themselves (in their intended occupations) from high and low status occupations into middle status occupations. The movement has continued for two generations and will apparently continue in the near future as the respondents themselves, with their relatively high level of education move from.their parents' social position and into middle status positions. Furthermore, when one resides and conducts research in all areas of the nation, he becomes aware that subtle variations in the rigidity of the system of social status also exist. In short, the relatively peripheral areas of the nation tend to be more rigidly stratified than the central areas. No doubt this has to do with the nature of class relationships derived from the continued, though passing, peripheral dependence on an agrarian paternalistic society common to most of Latin America under Iberian influence. Given the monumental lack of social data related to Costa Rica, one cannot quantify such impressions except by reference to the interhgenerational Table 2.4 above, which shows the proportional decline with continuing development of the nation of the extreme classes and the growth of the middle status sector. These observations are consistent with Linz's observations in Spain in which he identifies a series of cultural sub-groups, which differ largely in their relationship to the process of socio- economic development. Linz and his colleague Amanda deMiguel hare 61 emowo m.c ooosomawom Hon Homeosaosa.m weanou. mumsawmaaon can moww. mm Hooouaoa ow Homooooooe. consumawos mom osmommmenou reason mouw* m.«m.d¢m 5 I .ka 1* 5 I dub 5 a... Qw# mm 5 «a 5 mm 5 wfloouwodmfl% Actsonm ow HmHmo mafia 8. 3333 as 3: ta 3.: we 33 wuowommuosmp. snowmoswmw nQfi A QMV mN& AthV mefi AcaQV 3pmlmowwo Boflormsa. :32. 853. 4a A as Ga 303 3a A33 wflooflwodofl ow «mew campy dsmuoomm. canoe oooflwdoa oH mwwwwom Hosea 0H sswwousom moHministers in the current government? Scoring Procedure: 1. ’assign score of 2 for each fully correct answer. 1 for partially correct answer 2. sum scores. range 0-10 3. trichotomise according to observed groupings of scores Interest and attention index IIII'IIIIIIIV'I'" _ 195 Type: Additive two item index Source: Original Items: 1. 2. Do you have much interest in national politics? 3.. Much. b. Some. c. Almost non. d. None. Approximately how often do you listen to the national news on the radio or TV or read it in the newspapers? a. Daily. b . Weekly 0 c 0 Monthly. d. Several times a year. e. Rover. Scoring’Procedure: 1. 2. 3. 4. assign 4 to answer a of-#1, 3 to be, etc. 0 for blank assign 5 for answer a of #2, 4 to c, etc. 0 for blank sum.sccres. range from 2-9 (eliminate all respondents from index who failed to answer either question) trichotomize according to natural observed groupings of scores Part V. 'Attitudes toward traditional values and toward social change 1. Traditionalism Type: Additive index Source: Items: 1. David Smith and Alex Inkeles, "The GM Scale: A Comparative Socio-Psychological Measure of Individual MOdernity," Sociometry, XXIX, No. 4 (December, 1966), pp. 353-377. Adapted by author. One ought not believe the ideas of a stranger without first checking'them.with a friend. a. Agree strongly. b. Agree somewhat. c. Disagree somewhat. d. Disagree strongly. e. I don't know. 19C 2. You can say what you want about hard work getting people ahead, but the main thing that determines success is luck. a. Agree strongly. b. Agree somewhat. c. Disagree somewhat. d. Disagree strongly. e. I don't know. 3. A good son always accepts the political ideas of his father. a. Agree strongly. b. Agree somewhat. c. Disagree somewhat. d. Disagree strongly. e. I don't know. 4. If you have the opportunity to hire someone in your work, it is always best to give the job to a relative rather than to a stranger. a. Agree strongly. b. Agree somewhat. c. Disagree somewhat. d. Disagree strongly. e. I don't know. Scoring Procedure: 1. assign a score of 4 for each response a, 3 for b, 8120. 2. Eliminate from index any respondent with a ”don't know" response in any item 3. Sum scores. range from 4-16 4. trichotomize on basis of observed groupings ”1111111111111[111111111111111111111s 5052