THE E’FFECYEVENESS 0F RELIEF ; EEECREES iN AMEMERGER CASES Thesis far the Segree of Ph; Ex - MECHEGANSTATEEENNERSEW ' ‘ KENNETH? e3 ELZENGA; 1957 “1‘! LD l; 'Jllllal'rr'ru. 1.3.3 Kg. } ‘ LIBRARY Michig: :3 8:, University f V.» ‘PJ'A ~ am: This is to certifg that the thesis entitled THE EFFECTIVENESS OF RELIEF DEGREES IN ANTIMERGER CASES. presented by KENNETH GERALD ELZINGA has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph. D. degree in Economics [Oat gig/3a flfjmé am pm Date September ll, 1967 0-169 r —..L.h___._v_fl__ W_§.w—_‘. .mufifln‘..- , ._._ -.._ __ . _ mm: ABSTRACT THE EFFECTIVENESS OF RELIEF DEGREES IN ANTIMERGER CASES by Kenneth G. Elzinga The federal government's enviable and, at times, surprising record of victories,in antimerger cases neces- sitates-the enactment of relief. Relief is simply-the» action designed to prevent or undo the unlawful effects of a merger. The problem in-this thesis is to evaluate the: effectiveness of the relief.decrees obtained in antimerger cases-and identify any obstacles to the formulation of satisfactory relief. This, then, is an economic-study of what has happened after a merger case has been found either in violation of the law or the respondents have submitted to a consent decree. The study rests on the notion that an effective anti- merger statute requires effective relief;.that failure to secure effective relief will lead to two results: first, competition will not be restored in those markets where antimerger cases have been brought and, second, the law will not be a bar to those potential mergers which might have a deleterious effect on competition. A theory of relief is presented in the thesis which enables one to predict effective relief from observing three phenomena: the independence of the divested firm, Kenneth G. Elzingal its Viability, and the time span required to secure relief. From this theory a methodology is developed which allows the classification of actual relief decrees according to how they meet certain criteria. ‘These criteria are out- lined in the thesis. A sample.of antimerger cases is drawn, 39 in all, and using the above methodology, are classifiedas to their relief effectiveness. The data used to enable-this classi— fication are taken primarily from docket files and com- pliance reports at the Federal Trade Commission and. pleading files at the Department of Justice, Antitrust Division., The sample cases are then placed on a continuum to draw them together and give an overview of antimerger relief. The continuum has A categorieszw Successful, Sufficient, Deficient, and Unsuccessful relief. Of the 39 cases, the-A categories have 6, A, 8, and 21 occupants respectively. Thus, about three-fourths of the sample cases are Deficient or Unsuccessful in their relief by the standards used. For the purist who is concerned about the time span required to secure relief, a second continuum is developed. By adding this time standard, more than three— fourths of the sample cases are found in the category of. Unsuccessful relief. Specific obstacles to the securing of effective: relief are cited and supported with examples from the Kenneth G. Elzinga sample cases and other antimerger actions. These obstacles include the problem of physically restoring a firm after.it- has been absorbed into another, the problem of deciding what part or parts of the acquired firm to divest, and the problem of selecting an appropriate buyer. Special- attention is paid to the-government’s propensity to substi— tute marketing orders in lieu of structural relief. The- marketing orders.have distinguished themselves for being ineffective, difficult and/or costly-to-enforce, and generally protective in nature—-as.well as being repugnant, to the concept of antitrust. Three public policy measures are discussed.’ The- first-deals with facilitating structural relief after a merger is found to have violated the law. The second deals with stopping anticompetitive mergers before they are even. consummated. And the last considers the possibility of requiring companies planning to merge to first notify the: government of their intentions. THE EFFECTIVENESS OF RELIEF DEGREES IN ANTIMERGER CASES B y\b (0’ Kenneth G 3” Elzinga A THESIS Submitted to Michigan StateUniversity in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics_ 1967 {Ark-.5 TO KABE iii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS- I shall dispense with the usual paragraph stating what is obvious: that I have freely availed myself of the labors of numerous people, and it is impossible to acknowledge them all. There are, however, some individuals and organizations I would like to single out for a word of appreciation. I owe a special debt to the Federal Trade Commission, not only for providing me with an office during my research stay in Washington, but for cooperating with me while I was there in ways "far beyond the call of duty." Of all those at the Commission who were kind and helpful to me, I' should like.to mention four: Mr. Carl Batter of the. Compliance Division, and Miss Mary Ann Comps, Mr. Tom Hogarty, and Dr. Willard Mueller, of the Bureau of Economics. I might add that the FTC's library stands out asva place for research in antitrust. At the Antitrust Division of the; Department of Justice, the staff-in the Legal Records' Section was helpful to me, and I'm grateful for the use of the Divisionfls library. Special thanks are extended to those who provided me with my financial support:. the Ford Foundation and the Department of-Economics at Michigan State University. iv In a very meaningful sense, there are several professors I could mention whose endeavors have contributed to this: thesis. I shall mention only two. Professor Thomas Moore, provided assistance and encouragement during my research and read the manuscript. I'm grateful to him for his criticisms. To Professor Walter Adams goes a special word of appreciation. He not only wrestled with the obscurities of my early drafts but also was the source of considerable guidance in my thinking about the relief problem in-antitrust. Indeed my~ debt to him goes beyond this thesis-efor-during my graduate - studies he has often been a valued mentor, counselor, and- provocateur. My wife possesses virtues of patience and under- standing. For displaying these towards me, as well as being a source of encouragement, I'm grateful. But of course, for what follows, I must assume responsibility. TABLE OF CONTENTS DEDICATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF APPENDICES . . . . . . . . .-. . . .~. . . INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . .3. . . . . . . . Chapter I. MERGERS . . . . . . . . . . ... . . . . . Introduction~ Definition of Terms The Theory of-Mergers Mergers and Economic-Analysis Mergers and Monopoly Obstacles to Monopolization by Merger Overcoming the Obstacles American Experience with Mergers and MonOpoly ' Mergers and Promoters The Promotion of Mergers Today Mergers and Managers Managerial Incentives to Merge Mergers for Investment Private Advantages of External Growth, External Growth and Economic PrOSperity Mergers and Efficiency‘ The Tenuous Relationship of Mergers and Economies of Scale Mergers and Taxes Mergers for Sellers Mergers and Their Control by Law Mergers and Freedom of Contract Mergers and Free Markets: The Control of Mergers and Internal Expansion Mergers and Their Protection Conclusion vi Page iii iv ix Chapter Page II. THE ENFORCEMENT OF THE ANTIMERGER LAW . . . . . 38 Introduction The Original Section 7 The Failure of the Original Section 7 The Amended Section 7 The Mechanics of Antimerger Enforcement The Remedies The Scope of Antimerger Relief Guidelines for Antimerger Relief The Standards of Enforcement The Determination of a Relevant Market The Structure of the Relevant Market Additional Standards of_Enforcement Conclusion III. THE EFFECTIVENESS OF CELLER-KEFAUVER RELIEF . . 58 The Theory of Effective Relief The MethodOlogy of Pure,Relief The Test of Survival The Methodology Rejected The Methodology of This Study The Sample The Continuums; Exhibit II The SUCCESSFUL Relief Category The SUFFICIENT Category The DEFICIENT Category The UNSUCCESSFUL Category Conclusions from Exhibit.II Exhibit III. Average Time Spans Conclusions IV. THE REASONS FOR INEFFECTIVE RELIEF . . . . . .' 78 A Short Prelude on the Relief Problem Specific Problems hiAntimerger Relief. Asset Restoration The Time Factor The Problem of the Partial Divestiture' The Handling of Improvements The Buyer Problem Finding Any Buyer Finding the Right Buyer The Marketing Order~ The Future Ban The Environment of Antimerger Enforcement Conclusions vii Chapter Page V. PUBLIC_POLICY IMPLICATIONS . . . . . . . . . . 138 Introduction The Cost of Violating Section 7 The Cost of Litigation The Cost of Divestiture The Profitability of Violating Section 7 Section 7 Violation and Market Entry Implications for Public Policy Facilitating Structural Relief The'Spin-Off. The Spin -Off and Taxation Preliminary Injunctions Granting a Preliminary Injunction The Strategy of Opposing Preliminary Injunctions: In Support of Preliminary.Injunctions Facilitating Preliminary Relief: Premerger Notification Premerger Notification Legislation Drafting a Notification Statute Other Objections to Notification VI. CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180 The "Real" Impact of Section 7 The "Real" Impact and the FortuneJSOO The "Real" Impact and the Dairy Industry The "Real" Impact and the Cement Industry The "Real" Impact Upon-Past-Violators The "Real" Impact and Diversification Section 7 and Aggregate Concentration The Rising Tide of Aggregate Concentration Mergers and Aggregate Concentration The Future of Relief: The Judicial Front Encouraging Developments with the Judiciary An Old Story Repeated The Administrative Front The Commission!s Rulemaking Policy A Concluding Note on the Market as a Force for Relief BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205 APPENDICES O 0 O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O O O 0 O O 223 viii LIST OF APPENDICES- Appendix Page A. The Sample Cases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223 B. Aggregate Complaint and Divestiture Values from Chapter III . . . . . . . ._. . . . . . 278 . 280 C. Average Time Spans . . . . . . . . . . .,. ._ ix ,, mum, I INTRODUCTION Almost a decade ago, writing on the federal anti- merger law and a recent Supreme Court interpretation of that statute, Harbeson raised the question: Has the Clayton Act, Specifically its antimerger provision, been the "sleeping giant of antitrust?"1 Today there are many who would answer that question in the affirmative. From legal periodicals, economics journals, and the business press one might readily conclude that the "giant" is, for better or for worse, very much "awake." The federal antimerger law, as amended in 1950, has now been subjected to sufficient judicial scrutiny to yield . a feeling among many antitrust lawyers that the rules now established by the courts give Section 7 such broad SCOpe that the extent of its application to conventional horizontal and vertical mergers will in large part depend upon work-allocation and policy decision in the Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission.2 In other words there seems to be the general impres— sion in both the legal and business communities that the present antimerger law has become a "stronger" law than anyone would have predicted, that the government agencies enforcing the antimerger law have ample precedent to emerge victorious from any antimerger suit they bring, that any firm's decision to merge hinges not so much on the question of "is it legal" but rather ”will it be prosecuted," and finally that this law offers new hope for those who have long argued the wisdom of a strict application of the anti— trust laws to interfirm collusion and consolidation.3 The government's enviable and, at times, surprising record of victories in antimerger suits necessitates the enactment of relief. In nonetechnical terms, relief is simply the action designed to prevent or undo the unlawful effects of a merger, i.e. an action to maintain or bring about a state of compliance with the law. In a litigated case, relief follows the finding that a merger either will or has violated the law. When the respondent elects to settle the suit by a consent decree, the relief is simply that action, flowing from the settlement, which will satisfy the government that the purposes of the statute are being met. The relief that has been obtained by the government in antimerger cases is the object of study in this thesis. In short this is an economic study of the "back—side" of the antimerger law——what has happened after a merger case has been found in violation of the law or the respondents have decided to no longer fight the suit and instead submit to a consent decree. At the outset I stress that this is not another attempt to evaluate the develOping case law and the standards of legality under Section 7. For the most part these will assume the position of a "given" in this analysis and will be commented upon only in an ancillary sense. The main concern will be with the economic effec— tiveness of relief in these cases and the obstacles to the formulation of satisfactory relief. The study rests on the logical notion that an effec— tive antimerger statute requires effective relief; that, if mergers which violate the standards of the law are not subjected to meaningful relief, two results will follow: first, competition will not be restored in those markets where antimerger cases have been brought and, second, the law will not be a bar to those potential mergers which might have a deleterious effect on competition. Or as Justice Jackson put it, a court victory san§_effective relief means the government "has won a lawsuit and lost a cause."4 There has been a rather prodigious commentary on the legal and economic aspects of the developing case law under the federal antimerger statute; the literature is quite exhaustive-—and exhausting. But the question of adequate relief has been a neglected area of critical discussion. While some of the legal questions relating to the relief problem have been explored,5 economic analyses of the relief problem in antimerger enforcement have been con- spicuously absent. What follows is an effort to fill the lacuna. This study will begin with a short section on the "what" and ”why" of mergers. A short synopsis on the theory of mergers is offered pointing to why mergers are --——-r3- . consummated, when they are consummated, and why some are (or should be) outlawed. In Chapter II the law on mergers will be outlined. The relevant law for the purpose of this study is the 1950 Celler—Kefauver amendment to Section 7 of the Clayton Act. The factors leading to the passage of this amendment, its legislative history, the mechanics of its enforcement, the remedies available under the law, and the standards of enforcement found in the new Section 7 will be summarized as necessary background to the understanding of the relief problem. The following two chapters are the heart of the study. Chapter III outlines the methodology of the economic analy— sis of relief; the sample cases drawn for study are pre— sented and the sample is rated and evaluated. The reasons for ineffective relief are found in Chapter IV. These are drawn from both the history of the relief problem in antitrust law and from Specific instances in recent antimerger cases. The public policy implications of the study are explored in Chapter V. Various measures have been proposed to make relief more effective; these are considered there. This chapter also contains a short digression on the eco— nomic costs of violating Section 7 and what this might indicate for Section 7 enforcement. Chapter VI, the conclusion, will contain a summary of the study and some final thoughts on the real impact of relief in antimerger cases. FOOTNOTES INTRODUCTION 1Robert H. Harbeson, "The Clayton Act: Sleeping Giant of-Antitrust?" AER, A8 (March, 1958), pp. 92-104. 2Analysis, The Supreme Court's Merger Opinions," BNA Antitrust and Trade Regulation Repert, No. 162, p. B-A. 3For example see: Paul W. Cook, "Merger Law and Big Business: A Look Ahead," New York University_Law Review, 40 (October, 1965), pp. 710-72“; Sidney Fish, "Antitrust Landmark Cases," Journal of Commerce, June 21, 1965, p. 3; Milton Handler, "Mergers" in "Recent Anti— trust Developments," Michigan Law Review, 63 (November, 1964), pp. 67-78; "The Government Always Wins," editorial in WSJ, June 16, 1966, p. 16. ”International Salt Co. vu'U. S., 332 U.S. 392 at 401 (19A7). 5See: Thomas F. Daly, "Current Trends in Relief under Clayton Act Section 7," Dickinson Law Review, 70 (Fall, 1965), pp. 1—49; Robert B. Duke, "Scope of Relief Under Section 7 of the Clayton Act," Columbia Law Review, 63 (November, 1963), pp. 1192-1211; William T. Kerr, "Divestiture of Illegally Held Assets: Observations on its Scope, Objective, and Limitations," Michigan Law Review, 64 (June, 1966), pp. 1574-1599. III? CHAPTER I MERGERS "The main objective of growth through acquisition in a few cases seems to be to permit executives to fly bigger DC—3's."l Introduction The union of two companies by merger is not unlike the union of two peOple by marriage. Both peOple and companies of widely varying types join forces together and both unions are entered for a variety of reasons. Though many firms and many couples unite voluntarily, others are, to some degree, coerced into their bonds. Similarly, marriage, either corporate or personal, has no definite outcome. For some it will be a union of bliss; for others it will end (or even continue) unhappily. In this chapter a brief background account on the merger of business firms will be presented. The chapter's purpose is to introduce the subject of mergers, for such an introduction is a necessary condition to understanding the central topic of this study. Definition of Terms There are many terms suggestive of the combining of one business enterprise with another. The term "merger" has already been used. Others which come to mind are: acquisition, amalgamation, combination, consolidation, and take—over. This multiplicity of terms stems primarily from the multiplicity of ways in which two firms can be joined. For tax, legal, and financial reasons, the actual form and manner in which a union is consummated varies. In its well—known report on mergers, the Federal Trade Commission noted: The form of organization used in acquisition and mergers seems to follow no definite pattern but to vary in accordance with what appears to the promoters to be the best procedure in relation to the particular combination of conditions involved. A new company may be incorporated by joint effort to function as the acquiring firm; the acquirer, without change in name or corporate organization, may take over the stock or assets, in whole or in part, of another corporation; the acquirer may merely change its name, its form of organization, or its capital structure, in order to take over another corporation; the acquirer may organize a new subsidiary to purchase the stock or assets of another firm; the acquiring corporation may have an existing subsidiary purchase another corpora— tion; or other procedures may be followed when they will more satisfactorily meet the requirements at hand.2 Important as these tax—legal—financial distinctions are to the companies involved in a transaction of this sort, they are of little concern here. In the United States the union of two business firms is most generally referred to as a merger or an acquisition and in this study these terms will predominate. The term "merger" seems to imply the union of companies of similar size while an "acquisition" suggests that the acquiring firm is larger than the acquired firm. But for the purposes of this study any differences between these two terms will be overlooked. "Merger" and "acquisition" will be used in a generic sense as encompassing the several forms in which two or more previously independent business entities come under one corporate center of control.3 Using these terms synonymously is not unusual, even within the business community. In fact, perhaps the crucial difference between "acquisition" and "merger" is psychological. One source suggests that when a company approaches another it wants to buy, it talks merger to them but talks acquisition with its own board of directors and stockholders. It's not unusual to see why: . managements find comfort in the merging of mutual interests. Being acquired connotes being had! The Theory of Mergers5 More important than how mergers are consummated is why_they are consummated. When an announcement of two firms merging is made for public consumption, the reasons offered generally include such edible platitudes as ”to enable us to expand operations" or "to operate more effi— ciently" or "to more effectively meet competition." Note that all of these would indicate the public to be the true beneficiary: the implication being that the public will now receive more goods, produced with fewer resources, and sold at a lower price. lO Mergers and Economic Analysis But these assertations neither answer nor demonstrate h9w_the public is to obtain these benefits. Economic analysis on the other hand does shed some light on this business practice, for the phenomenon of merging has solid grounding in economic theory. Economic analysis would lead to the following pre— diction about merging: assuming rational economic behavior on the part of managers, the merger route to expansion would be followed when, ceteris paribus, it increases the value of the enterprise by more than the cost of the acqui— sition and increases it to a greater extent than would be possible by either building the facilities or taking some alternative action-—like doing nothing. In more obvious parlance, mergers are made for money! Mergers and Mongpoly But economic theory goes much deeper than just saying mergers are made for money. Economic theory enables one to predict a tendency for horizontal mergers to occur, to pre— dict under what institutional circumstances they are more likely to occur, and it has something to say about the effect of allowing this consolidation of competitors to take place. It is a corollary of economic analysis that industry profits are maximized (or losses minimized) when output is produced at a rate which equalizes marginal revenue with ll marginal cost.6 Consequently firms in an industry would find it to their economic advantage to forego independent action and instead CQOperate in operating at this rate of maximum short—run gain. Obstacles to MonOpolization by Merger But there are well—known obstacles in the path of an industry's attempt to rationalize its production by some cartel-like policy of cooperation. First, the firms in the industry might be unable to determine that rate of output which maximizes short—run profits. Second, they might be unable satisfactorily to assign the necessary production quotas and divide the profits among themselves. Third, the lure of the monopoly profits could attract new resources to the industry; gage some barrier to entry and, given the other difficulties, the established firms might be reluctant to cooperate for this reason. Fourth, the incentive to remain outside a cartel or the incentive to cheat as a member of a cartel, probably more than any other factor, hampers attempts to rationalize the industry rate of pro— 7 duction. And, finally, such arrangements might be illegal. Overcoming the Obstacles Economic analysis enables us to predict that some form of cooperation to obtain these monopoly gains is more likely to occur the more readily the established firms in an industry are able to overcome these formidable obstacles. For example, an industry into which new entry has been 12 forbidden by the government and where the existing firms are few in number would be a likely candidate for rationaliza— tion. But without government protection, a group of inde— pendent firms would probably not be able to form a cartel capable of securing monopoly profits for any long period of time. There are too many weaknesses in the cartel form of industry organization. If loose-knit business coalitions are susceptible to failure, one would predict another type of coalition to be sought which might be more successful. Coalition by merging offers such a possibility. Whenever rivals can be acquired for less than the capitalized earnings which would come from their being skillfully operated as part of a consoli— dated firm with great market power, such consolidations will be made if the financial-legal institutions of the economy so allow. Again, as with cartels, one would not predict ration— alization via merging to occur unless some barrier to entry was possible. And merging can make this possible since the merging form of rationalizing an industry has two inherent advantages over the cartel. First, the consolidated firm isbetter able to exclude or hinder newcomers than its loose—knit counterpart.8 And, second, a tight coalition has fewer administrative problems than its loose counter— part. "t 13 American Experience with Mergers and Monopoly‘ This tendency to rationalize an industry Via merger, which would be predicted by economic analysis, manifested itself in the U.S. as soon as the legal—financial institu— tions permitted.9 When capital markets were developed, state incorporation laws allowed greater capitalizations and wider areas of operation, and the federal law looked askance on cartelization but did not blink at consolida— a merger movement was ushered into the American indus— 0 tion, trial scene which transformed its structure radically.l Writing about this first great merger movement, Nelson's research led him to conclude: It transformed many industries, formerly characterized by many small and medium sized firms, into those in which one or a few very large enterprises occupied leading positions. . . . The huge turn—of—the—century merger wave produced U.S. Steel, American Tobacco, International Harvester, duPont, Corn Products, Anaconda Copper, and American Smelting and Refining, to name only a few. Its effect on American industry was widespread and enduring. Verily, the first merger movement validated what would be predicted from economic analysis about horizontal mergers. The inability to secure permanent barriers to entry, coupled with the probably recalcitrance of some firms to join the consolidation,meantthat the merger route would seldom end in complete monopolization. But, given the opportunity, firms would combine) the incentive for doing so being monopoly profits. In his survey article on mergers, Markham concluded: 14 In the steel, tobacco products, petroleum refining, sugar refining, nonferrous metal smelting, shoe machinery, typewriter, and other industries, it is quite clear that mergers transformed oligopolistic or competitive markets into markets dominated by partial monopolists frequently controlling over 50 per cent of total output. In short, the aim of such mergers clearly must have been monopoly, although it was never perfectly achieved and rarely if ever displaced anything resembling perfect com— petition. This is not to imply in any way that all mergers have as their goal or even their hope the securing of monopoly profits. Far from it. But suffice it to say that mergers have led to the securing of considerable market power in some industries and, without some legal obstacle, there will remain a tendency for industries to be rationalized through consolidation. To be able to "explain" all mergers as attempts to alter the location and elasticity of the acquiring firm's demand curve would be handy—-but it would be incorrect. To be sure, establishing this "pressure" for horizontal con— solidation is certainly an important contribution to under— standing the merger phenomenon. But, as was indicated in the introduction to this chapter, mergers do not lend them— selves to any one raison d'etre except that they take place for money. And one way they can "make money" is via the rationalization of an industry. But there are other ways as well. f L?! l5 Mergers and Promoters The heavy demand for securities during most of the first merger movement provided a new type of entrepreneur on the financial scene--the promoter of mergers. Noting the high degree of Speculation in asset values and the opportunity to float additional securities on already existing assets when offered in a ”new package," promoters were quick to lecture prospective stock buyers on the expected monOpoly gains from their consolidations. In many cases the monOpoly gains failed to materialize; the net result of these endeavors was the sale of considerable water made possible by imperfect knowledge on the part of the buyers. Thus, one stimulus to mergers, distinct from any desire to rationalize an industry, is the desire to obtain private financial gain——even to the detriment of the firms involved. While this method achieved great notoriety during the financial manipulations of the past, the stimulus itself is still present. Imperfect knowledge by buyers in the capital market can still enable this sort of promoting to occur though certainly not on the scale once possible. The Promotion of Mergers Today This stimulus to effectuate mergers for promoter's profits manifests itself today in the large number of pri- vate firms, investment houses, business brokers, and other financial institutions interested in promoting business l6 unions. Fortunately, these firms whose business is corporate marriage promotion cannot long survive if their promotions are done only to their gain and to the detriment of the joined companies. Mergers and Managers There is another interesting hypothesis about mergers which is indirectly related to the promoter—profit stimulus. In the heyday of watered stocks, the promoter made his money in the form of a short—term capital gain. He did not consider himself a manager of the consolidated-firm in any meaningful sense, nor did he plan to be a long—term stock- holder. But it was in his private interest to promote mergers. The modern counterpart to such promotions may be the management of the large corporation. Here again considera- tions of corporate profits and loss may become of secondary importance as the desire to enhance private managerial gain, either pecuniary or non—pecuniary, becomes primary. Is it not possible that these private managerial goals might be best met via the merger route? This is neither the time nor the place to discuss the possible conflicts between sales maximization and profit maximization or possible conflicts between divergent goals of the firm and goals of its management.13 This can only lead into a tangential discourse on the theory of the firm. Suffice it to say but two things. r. n. A l7 Managerial Incentives to Merge First, to the extent that managerial salaries are tied to "business size"124 and management is motivated to increase the size of its salaries, one would predict mergers to take place.15 To the extent that managerial aspirations are tied to being associated with large, growing, prestigious firms, one would also predict mergers to take place. For, without question, mergers are a very quick route to corporate growth. Second, that managerial aspirations may be so inclined is still an Open issue. Baumol, commenting on his observa— tions of, and experiences with, contemporary corporate life concluded that . in talking to business executives one may easily come to believe that growth of thelgirm is the main preoccupation of top management. Two recent studies from one of the bastions of behavioral—firm—theorizing support the hypothesis that mergers can serve the private interests of managers and are consummated for this reason; that corporate growth, in and of itself, can be a goal of the firm; and that this mana- gerial desire for growth can manifest itself in mergers which do not further the interests of stockholders.17 Merging can not only meet private managerial goals of the acquiring firm but could also dovetail nicely with pri— vate managerial goals of the acquired firm. This could be an important stimulus to mergers. One neglected British author put it this way: l8 . (in some cases) control over the assets of a company can be obtained by obtaining control of the administration of a company. . . . By dealing with and taking over the position of the existing con— trollers of the company, the prospective purchaser may be able to acquire control over the assets for considerably less than the full value of the assets. . . . The existing controllers are there— fore frequently in a position to pass control . on terms which secure to themselves the whole or a diSproportionate part of the consideration passing from the purchaser.1 These favorable ”terms" might be in the form of good manage— ment positions with the new company, lucrative stock options, or even outright cash bonuses. The implications of this line of reasoning do not call for a rejection of the neo—classical profit maximizing calculus as a tool for predicting firm behavior. It is included only to suggest that of the various stimuli that can cause mergers, the managerial desire ”to fly bigger DC—3's" can be, and no doubt has been, one of them. Mergers for Investment " ”mergers for pro— Aside from "mergers for monopoly, moters," and "mergers for managers," one firm may acquire another (or others) solely for rational investment reasons. For, in a most meaningful sense, an acquisition decision by the acquiring firm is a decision to invest. One firm sees an opportunity to acquire another with the expectation, perhaps based only on faith in synergism, of making sub- stantial earnings on the purchase. Weston reports investment motives to be of great importance in the acquisition decisions of companies. In l9 one—half of the cases examined, acquisitions were in response to a decision to invest in a new plant, a new product, or a new product organization.19 Private Advantages of External Growth These investment decisions often lead to an acquisi- tion instead of internal expansion since, ceteris paribus, acquisitions normally take less time, involve less un— certainty, and are easier to finance. And of course buying rather than building offers the additional advantage of eliminating a rival in the process! This suggests an explanation for many of the diversi- fication acquisitions which have been made since World War II. To the extent that larger diversified firms have lower capitalization rates expressed in their earnings-stock price ratios, and smaller more specialized firms have higher l rates, and to the extent that the recorded income of the l latter, if acquired by the former, will be capitalized by j the market at the acquiring firm's rate, the acquisition will add more to the market value of the acquirer than the cost of acquiring the Specialized firm. Therefore, one would predict such acquisitions to be made——and they have been.20 Probably the majority of the post—war acquisitions can be best eXplained as decisions to invest. They are business transactions of a rather conventional sort——mani— festations of an opportunity to diversify, to become 20 vertically integrated, to move into a new geographic market, or round out a product line. External Growth and Economic Prosperity Support for the notion that mergers are strongly induced by investment considerations comes from their core relation with business indicators; prosperity in the busi- ness sector is positively correlated with merger activity. Weston correlated merger activity with three business indicators and found their correlation with industrial stock prices to be significant.21 Nelson found mergers to respond positively and with regularity to the business cycle.22 Mueller studied merger rates in a particular industry, the dairy industry-—one heavily hit by merger activity, and found a tight statistical association between mergers and industrial stock prices. To the extent that stock prices are a reliable indi— : cator of business expectations, one would predict rising stock prices to be associated with business expansion plans. And since the merger route is often the advantageous eXpansion course for a business enterprise, ". . . prOSperity accelerates mergers because it accelerates business expan— sion."24 L m A 21 Mergers and Efficiency Merging companies are prone to ascribe increases in efficiency as the prime impetus in their union. And this may be the case. But to attribute economies of scale as the stimulus to many mergers is an assertion resting on a wobbly foundation. Of course, almost ggy_statement on economies of scale rests on an unsteady base since the theory, and a fortiori the measurement, of firm Optimality 25 is still an unsatisfactory notion in economics. The Tenuous Relationship of Mergers and Economies of Scale Certainly acquiring another firm does not directly increase production economies of scale in the sense of causing a move to a lower point on the firm's average cost curve. Nor does an acquisition increase economies of scale in the sense of replacing an existing plant with one having a lower average cost curve. In any meaningful sense of the term, a merger can contribute to economies of scale only in the sense that the combined firm can obtain factors of production, marketing services, or capital, cheaper than before the merger. And this is desirable only if the lower prices do not stem from an increase in the firm's monopsony power. Consequently, the economies—of-scale—by—merger argument must rest on some rather subtle ground—-for the economies must be of the multi-plant variety rather than the more 22 efficient plant size breed. It is worthy to note that merger scholars have not been impressed by obvious signs of economies of scale in their studies. Nelson noted even in the first merger movement, where so many of the mergers were horizontal and should have been more susceptible to economies of scale, that these mergers occurred in such a variety of industries which had such divergent production processes that the scale economies argument "is hard to believe."26 Heflebower judged purported economies from 27 There are no data in Weston's study merger as "tenuous." to lead one to conclude that economies of scale were a prime motive for, or result of, merging.28 Markham, while accenting the "complex and diverse" causes of mergers never stresses economies of scale as a central cause, choosing instead to wave mainly the flags of promoter profits, market 29 control, and ordinary investment decisions. Nor do economies of scale find a soft spot anywhere in Stigler's 3O contribution. After studying acquisitions of unrelated lines, Gort concluded that diversification decisions stimulated by expected economies of scale "are not very frequent."31 This is certainly not to say that mergers have not made some firms more efficient. No doubt there have been many cases where vertical acquisitions have enabled an acquiring firm to plan its production more systematically; where acquiring a new product line, readily marketable with existing products, has reduced total marketing costs; 23 or where acquiring "new" management has had valuable synergistic effects on firm efficiency. But the relevant issues are: how often does this happen and is there an alternative way to secure these same economies? The avail— able evidence can only produce skepticism on the magnitude and frequency of these economies. If mergers were really prompted by cost-cutting considerations, one would predict their frequency to be inverse to the level of business activity, i.e. most frequent during business contractions. But this has not been the case. As to whether there is an alternative way to secure these economies, other than by merging, will be discussed later in this chapter. Mergers and Taxes The federal tax structure also lends encouragement to mergers, particularly from the seller's point of View. Both the federal income tax and estate tax are relevant here. The stockholders of a successful, closely held company pay a personal income tax on their dividend income. They have the Option of selling out and paying a capital gains tax of up to twenty—five per cent on any gain over their original investment. But an attractive option to these stockholders is to exchange their stock for stock in a listed company at a rate equal to their firm's fair market value. This involves no taxable gain or loss. If these stockholders have any inclination to exit, selling out via stock exchange ._._..__. ‘.__ .m‘ .-__. ._.—.— I .. . L a. l 2A to a listed firm would be the likely route; selling the firm as a new entrant is less likely. Pending estate taxes offer another incentive to be acquired if the firm is closely held by an aging owner. This stimulus is reinforced by the uncertainty of the value the Treasury will place on the business for estate tax purposes.32 To a lesser extent, the reorganization provisions of the federal Revenue Code promote acquisitions from the view— point of the acquiring company. This is particularly the case when the acquiring firm plans on liquidating its 33 acquisition within two years. Another tax impetus to the acquisition route occurs when a firm has a tax loss carry— over. At such times a firm may seek to acquire profitable enterprises then applying the loss carryover against the 3A consolidated taxable income. Mergers for Sellers To look at acquisitions only from the side of the acquiring firm's stimulus would be incomplete. The coin has another side. Many an acquisition has been consummated at the initiation of the selling firm. It was just shown how the federal tax structure could encourage firms to disappear by being acquired. But these tax reasons aside, there are a host of other reasons why businesses might seek out pur— chasers. Owners may wish to retire. There might be disen— sion among the present management or ownership. Or the firm L N i 25 might receive an offer it knows to be considerably more than the firm is worth! Interestingly, Mace and Montgomery, in their excellent contribution to merger scholarship, had this observation on selling out: In most, but not all, of the cases studied the one single factor which characterized the decisions to sell was fear: fear about the future; fear that the product line was outmoded; fear that while company—rich although cash poor, the capital accumu— lated in a lifetime would be lost; fear that tech— nology once reasonably simple was beyond the management's capacity to cope with; fear that key people were becoming dissatisfied with salary compensation and would leave to join enterprises where capital participation was possible.3 In testimony before a Senate subcommittee, the chair— man of the board of Burlington Industries said that of all the mergers Burlington had consummated, about one—half 36 The came at the initiation of the companies acquired. president of Borden also indicated this had been the case 37 in Borden's extensive acquisition efforts. Mergers and Their Control by Law It is a basic tenet of free enterprise capitalism that resources are best allocated by allowing the members of the economy to pursue their own individual economic advantage. Two necessary conditions for this pursuit of individual advantage are freedom of contract and sanctity of contract. Consequently, in free societies, one finds considerable emphasis placed on the right to enter con- tracts and the right to have them enforced. Al ‘14; ‘7‘- 1K1; ' 26 Mergers and Freedom of Contract Mergers are but one manifestation of people pursuing their own self—interest. And contracts are the legal vehicles for consummating mergers. Consequently, any law prohibiting the consummation of mergers would violate the freedom of contract and alter the allocation of resources. Similarly, a law against those mergers already consummated would violate the sanctity of the merger contract and, by dissolving the merger, alter the allocation of resources. Therefore, a prima facie case exists against barring mergers, for such a law violates two "freedoms." The burden of proof then is on the advocate of an antimerger law. He must show two things: first, that mergers egg interfere with free markets, thereby hindering others in their pursuit of gain and causing a resultant misallocation of resources; second, that those mergers which have such effects can be distinguished from those which are harmless or beneficial. Mergers and Free Markets Economic theory demonstrates analytically that pursuit of private gain in free markets leads to an efficient allocation of resources. Yet this same analysis, which so strongly supports a policy of free markets, also calls for a policy of limited intervention in some markets. For it is only when markets are fgeg, when individuals on either side have numerous alternatives, that the market system L m l 27 works. It is because of this orientation toward free markets that economic theory argues against some mergers. Economic theory argues particularly for limiting horizontal mergers. For horizontal mergers eliminate com— petitors and since competition is, in a very crucial sense, a function of the number of competitors in a market, the logical extension of horizontal merging can be monOpoly power. Consider the United State's first and second merger movements. As was indicated earlier, the first movement was characterized in several important industries by hori— zontal mergers aimed at dominating the industry, i.e. mergers for monopoly power. At the time of the first move— ment, there was no effective law against monopolizing. Unlike the first movement, the second did not result in industry domination by any one firm. Instead it ended in the oligOpolization of several key industries. While monopolization was by that time barred by the Sherman Anti— trust Act, there was no legal restraint on the oligopoliza— tion of an industry through merging. Consequently, a handful of firms in these industries undertook extensive merger programs which wrought high structural concentration.38 This experience of American industrial history indi— cates the need for some sort of antimerger legislation. Clearly mergers for monopoly are undesirable. And while oligopoly is a weaker form of monOpoly, it is no substitute for free markets. Had the United States, since the industrial 28 revolution, prohibited many of these mergers, it would now possess an industrial structure far less concentrated than presently exists. Of course, not only horizontal mergers can lead to market power. Vertical acquisitions can also do this under certain circumstances, namely when the acquiring firm already possesses market power somewhere in the verti— cal chain. When this is.the case, vertical acquisitions can lead to market foreclosure-—remaining non—integrated firms being cut off from a source of supply or from a customer for reasons not directly related to their own efficiency. Vertical integration can provide the leverage for an anticompetitive price policy designed to discipline 39 Vertical acquisi- or eliminate the non—integrated firm. tions are related to horizontal ones in that both can eliminate alternatives; and the existence of alternatives is the keystone to a free market. While market extension and product extension acquisi- tions do not eliminate competition between direct rivals, the impact upon free markets of continual merging of even this sort can be deleterious. As Markham put it: The merger of two actual competitors may sub— stantially injure competition in existence today, while the merger of two potential competitors may substantially injure competition expected tomorrow. When two firms produce the same product but in different geographic markets, each firm lives under the threat of the other entering his market and competing therein. A ,1" m A 29 market extension acquisition eliminates this threat. The~ analagous loss of potential competition possible by a product extension acquisition is obvious. Just as there is a need for limiting the freedom to merge when it leads to or results in market power, there is reason for impinging on this freedom if the impetus and result are promoters' profits or private managerial gains-— in the sense of "mergers for promoters" or "mergers for managers" as outlined earlier in this chapter. The existence of the former is made possible only through imperfections in the capital market and will cause a subOptimal allocation of resources. Similarly, the existence of the latter, with managers making decisions on a different basis than cost— revenue considerations, can also lead to a suboptimal allo— .“ cation of resources. Clearly, these stimuli run counter to economic policy and any mergers based on them should be checked. And what of efficiency and investment reasons for ‘h merging? Without doubt, it is in society's interest to allow, even protect, the right to merge for efficiency gains. But, as was indicated earlier, one must be skeptical of how often this occurs. While the effect of a firm's investment decision to eXpand by acquisition may seem innocuous enough, here again one must look behind the decision as one advantageous to the firm and consider in addition possible effects of this 30 decision on competition. Business expansion on the surface is a desirable thing. But expanding by merger, in and of itself, does not stimulate competition. And as has been (perhaps tediously) indicated, it can frustrate competition. The Control of Mergers and Internal Expansion' It is important to consider the effect on competition of the alternative to expansion by acquisition, namely building. Expanding by building new facilities not only does not eliminate a rival—~it adds capacity to the industry and, one might hope, downward pressure on prices. In addition, expansion by building provides a better market test of allocative optimality than eXpansion by acquiring—— since building means that the firm has either had to go into the capital market and compete for funds or has been efficient enough to generate them internally.M1 All too often companies try and leave the impression that if the merger route to expansion is closed to them, they will have no alternative way to grow. This is clearly nonsense. One of the most dramatic examples of this is found in the proposed Bethlehem—Youngstown merger. Arthur B. Homer, president of Bethlehem Steel, had the temerity to tell a Senate subcommittee: To forbid the proposed Bethlehem-Youngstown merger would mean that Bethlehem, which today has no productive capacity in the midcontinent area, would in effect be prevented from entering the markets in that area in competition with the many large steel companies there.u2 ._..‘._ ._.-fia—a — _ ._ . . _. ”._. .. 31 After the proposed merger was enjoined on the ground that it would eliminate substantial competition in the midwest steel market, Bethlehem began plans for the construction of a huge steel producing complex, costing four hundred “3 million dollars, at Burns Harbor, Indiana. This was built to serve the supposedly unenterable midwest area. In addi— A tion, following the decision barring this merger, Bethlehem's Lackawanna works at Buffalo, New York, which had served the midwest markets, came in for sixty-one million dollars worth of modernizationtLlLl 2 Similarly, in cases where companies have been ordered l by law to sell acquired facilities, it has not been uncommon for these firms to adOpt the building route to retain their market position after the merger route to expansion was blocked and negated. Mergers and Their Protection _.‘._.—.-._._._._......_-_. ._. . . Until now it may seem that the case for even allowing L mergers is, from society's viewpoint, fairly weak. But there is a very vital reason for not limiting this business . practice too rigidly. This reason is related to the last merger incentive considered-—"mergers for sellers." To be acquired is an important method of exiting from an industry. Financially, it is far better than exiting via bankruptcy. To eliminate this possibility of selling out to a going firm would severely limit the exit market. Since a totally "new" buyer for a going firm might be 32 difficult to find, and if it were unlawful to contract a sale with a going firm, the risk of doing business would increase. And an increase in risk can only serve to dampen entry. In short, the ability to exit from an industry must be protected to enhance the ease of entry. There is little doubt that an entrepreneur would be more reluctant to enter a particular industry knowing that if he is unsuccessful he will be unable to salvage his investment by selling out to an existing firm. Therefore, if the enforcement of a prohibition on mergers were to become too "strict," this would serve to lessen competition. As Adelman put it: The ability to sell a business is much like the ability to sell any other investment-~it is an inducement to attempt success, and an insurance against failure. Hence the formatiOn of new business firms . . . is increased by maintaining a market for going businesses. Manne presented another interesting argument for pro— tecting this right to merge. He argued that the option of merging provides to the stockholders, unable to effectuate a takeover, a protection against inefficient management. If the inefficiency of management is reflected in low stock prices, the firm becomes a likely acquisition candif date to a firm with sounder management. Preserving this "market for corporate control" by allowing this inefficient firm to be acquired protects stockholders with non— A6 controlling interests. 33 W Earlier, the statement was made that the case for limiting mergers must rest on two demonstrable premises: (1) that some mergers hindered the operation of free markets and (2) that these mergers can be singled out. Few would disagree that the first premise is readily demon- strable. The second, the actual selection of undesirable mergers, involves far more controversy. But even here the argument does not center around the notion of whether the undesirable mergers can be singled out or not. Nearly everyone agrees—fin principle——that they can. The disagree— ment commences when an ”undesirable" merger is selected in practice! For while the combatants may agree that selection is possible, the standards they would employ for singling out deleterious mergers might vary widely.“7 While it is beyond the scope of this study to elaborate on this issue, the next chapter will consider the standards which have been adopted in attacking mergers. It is only fair to point out what is probably already obvious. This study rests on the notion that prohibiting some mergers is desirable economic policy; that doing so can be an important step in preventing restraints of trade. Furthermore the study rests on the notion that, while the cost to society of any particular merger cannot be precisely calculated, the problem of barring economically undesirable mergers is not insurmountable. NJ FOOTNOTES CHAPTER I lMyles L. Mace and George G. Montgomery, Management Problems of Corporate Acquisitions (Boston: Division of Research,fGraduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1962), pp. 9—10. 2Report on Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions, Federal Trade Commission (1955), p. 87. 3These two terms also will encompass the five struc— tural categories of business combinations. These are: 1) horizontal mergers, the merging of competitors; 2) verti— cal mergers, the merging of companies in a buyer—seller relationship; 3) product extension mergers, the merging of companies producing products which do not compete directly but are functionally related in production or marketing; 4) market extension mergers, the merging of companies pro? ducing closely related products but in different geographic markets; 5) conglomerate mergers, the merging of companies not having any of the above relationships. “Mace and Montgomery, op. cit., pp. 3—4, underlining mine. 5In this chapter, my debt to the following three sources will be obvious: Donald Dewey, Mondpoly in Economics and Law (Chicago: Rand McNally & Co., 19597; chaps. Ilev; R.B. Heflebower, "Corporate Mergers: Policy and Economic Analysis," QJE, 77 (November, 1963), pp. 537-558; George: J. Stigler,_“Monopoly and Oligopoly by Merger,” AER Proceedings, A0 (May, 1950), pp. 23—34. 6Maximization also requires that marginal costs be’ increasing. 7See Dewey, op. cit., pp. 7—24, for a lucid discussion of cartel theory. 8Ibid., p. 27. gstigler, op. cit., p. 28. lOStigler, loc. cit., pp. 27—31; Jesse Markham, "Survey of the Evidence and Findings on Mergers," Business Concen— tration and Price Policy, Conference of the Universities— National Bureau for Economic Research (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1955), pp. 154—167; Ralph L. Nelson, Merger Movements in American Industry,gl895—l956 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1959), p. 5. 3A ’35 11Nelson, ibid., pp. 5 and 3“. 12Markham, op. cit., p. 158; see also Nelson, ibid., pp. 100-103. 13But see: Kenneth E. Boulding, "Present Position of the Theory of the Firm," Linear Programming and the Theory of the Firm, ed. K.E. Boulding and William A. Spivey (New York: Macmillan Co., 1960), pp. l—l7; Fritz Machlup, "Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral,Managerial," AER, 57 (March, 1967), pp. 1—33; A.G. Papandreou, "Some BEEIC Problems in the Theory of the Firm," Survey of Con- tem orar Economics, ed. B.F. Haley (Homewood, Ill.: R.D. Irwin, 19525, Vol. II, pp. 183—219. l”As measured by corporate sales or assets. 15McGuire, et. al., found executive compensation more closely tied to sales than to profits. See J.W. McGuire, J. S. Y. Chiu, and A. U. Elbing, "Executive Incomes, Sales and Profits,” AER, 52 (September, 1962), pp. 751—761. 16William Baumol, "On the Theory of the Expansion of the Firm," AER, 52 (December, 1963), p. 1078. 17John Bossons, Kalman J. Cohen, and Samuel R. Reid, I "Mergers for Whom——Managers or Stockholders?," Carnegie Institute of Technology Workshop on Capital Market Equili— ‘ brating Processes, Working Paper #14 (mimeo) April, 1966; Kalman J. Cohen and Samuel R. Reid, "Bank Mergers for Whom—— Managers, Stockholders, or the Public?," Carnegie Institute of Technology Workshop on Capital Market Equilibrating Processes, Working Paper #10 (mimeo) April, 1966. 18M. A. Weinberg, Take—Overs and Amalgamations (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1963), p. . ng. Fred Weston, The Role of Mergers in the Growth of Large Firms (Berkeley: Univ. of Calif. Press, 1953)5 p. 73 as adapted from J. Keith Butters, John Lintner, and William L. Cary, Effects of Taxation: Corporate Mergers (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 195I7. 20See Heflebower, op. cit., p. 55A; the lower ratio for the large diversified firm reflects the greater liquidity of holding shares in the large firm and the greater certainty of its income stream due to its diversi- fication. 36 21Weston, op. cit., p. 80. 22Nelson, op. cit., pp. 106-124; see also George D. McCarthy, Acquisitions and Mergers (New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1963), pp. 3-5. 23Testimony of Willard Mueller in U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Hearings, Economic Concentration, Pt. 2, 89th Cong., lst Sess., March—April, 1965, p. 506. 24lbid., p. 507. 25See Joel Dean and Winfield Smith, "Relationships between Profitability and Size," The Corporate Merger, ed. William Alberts and Joel Segall(Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1966), pp. 10-11; and Dewey, op. cit., pp. 30-31. 26Nelson, op. cit., pp. lO3—1OA. 27Hef1ebower, op. cit., p. 556. 28Weston, op. cit., pp. 62—85, esp. p. 81. 29Markham, op. cit., pp. 180—181. 0 3 Stigler, loco cit. 31Michael Gort, "Diversification, Mergers, and Profits," in Alberts & Segall (eds.) The Corporate Merger, op. cit., p. 33. 32John Lintner and Keith Butters, "Effects of Taxes on Concentration,” in Business Concentration and Price Policy, op. cit., pp. 268—274. The authors clearly indi— cate that tax considerations have not been a major impetus . to mergers, concluding that tax considerations often tend V to accelerate a sale as opposed to causing a sale. 33 \ McCarthy, op. cit., pp. 1A—15. \ l 3“Ibid., p. 13. \ 35Mace and Montgomery, op. cit., p. 33. 36U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Report, Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions, 85th Cong., lst Sess., March, 1957, p. 37. 37 37Ihid., p. 39. 38This is developed in more detail by George Stigler, op. cit., pp. 31-33. 39Walter Adams and Joel B. Dirlam, "Steel Imports and Vertical Oligopoly Power," AER, 54 (September, 1964), pp. 626—655. quesse Markham, "Merger Policy Under the New Sec— tion 7: A Six Year Appraisal, " Virginia Law Review, A3 (May, 1957), p. A97. ulOn the rationale of antimerger legislation, see Walter Adams and Joel B. Dirlam, "Brown Shoe: In Step with Antitrust," Washipgton Univ. Law Quarterly, 1963 (April, 1963), pp. 159—162. MZAS quoted in Joseph W. Burns, A Study of the Antitrust Laws (New York: Central Book Co., 1958), p. 296. MBWSJ, August 2“, 1965, p. 15. “MWSJ, June 15, 196A, p. 3. ”5M. A. Adelman, "Small Business—~A Matter of Definition, " A. B. A. Proceedings,,Section of Antitrust Law, ’> 16 (I960), 28— 29. M6Henry G. Manne, "Mergers and the Market for Corpor- ate Control," JPE, 73 (April, 1965), pp. 110-120. uYFor example compare: Heflebower, loc. cit. and George Stigler, "Mergers and Preventive Antitrust Policy,” Univ. of Penn. Law Review, 104 (November, 1955), pp. 176- 18A and Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1955), chap. III. CHAPTER II THE ENFORCEMENT OF THE ANTIMERGER LAW "Who is the dumb guy in charge of the Antitrust Division? They approved the Studebaker—Packer merger and won't approve the Bethlehem—Youngstown merger. I don't get it. How dumb can you get?" —-Letter to Department of Justice Introduction In Chapter I, the reasons mergers occur and the impact of mergers upon competition were examined. From this examination, the rationale for an antimerger law was established. The focus of attention now turns to the enforcement of such a law. The sections in this chapter describing the mechanics of antimerger enforcement and the remedies applicable to violations of an antimerger law provide a necessary background for the detailed examina- tion of antimerger relief that is to follow in Chapters III and IV. To complete this chapter, the judicial standards of enforcement which.emanate from the developing antimerger case law are presented. While an acquaintance with this material is important in understanding the central issue of this thesis, the reader who is well versed in antitrust law need only skim, if not skip over, this chapter. 38 ——’—i 39 The Original Section 7 The magnitude of the first merger movement, and the inability of the Sherman Act to deter monopolization, led Congress to single out for curtailment certain trade prac— tices which had as their effect the promulgation of monopoly. The manifestation of this concern was.the drafting and passage of the Clayton Act in 191“.1 The purpose of this act was . without amending the Sherman Act . . . to supplement that act by denouncing and making unlawful certain trade practices which, while not covered by that act because not amounting to restraint of commerce or monopoly in themselves, yet constitute elementp tending ultimately to violations of that act. Section 7 of that act dealt with mergers and provided (in part) as follows: . . . no corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share capital of another corporation engaged also in commerce where the effect of such acquisition may be to substantially lessen competition between the corporation whose stock is so acquired and the corporation making the acquisition . . . or~ tend to cpeate a monopoly of any line of commerce. The goal of this law was to stop anticompetitive mergers in their incipiency-—on the theory it was better to crush eggs than wrestle snakes. The Failure of the Original Section 7 It is one of the well—established, oft-documented conclusions of antitrust scholarship that the inept drafting 40 of the above law coupled with an unsympathetic judiciary produced another fiasco in the annals of antitrust.” For, under the original Section 7, the actual challenging of a merger was-a rare occurrence. The Antitrust Division played a "minor role in the administration of Section 7" prior to its amendment in 1950. From 1914 to 1950, it filed only £93; complaints and had but one settled in its favor, that being a case where the Sherman Act was also violated.5 The Federal Trade Commission tried harder, but~ it too was without much success. From 1927 to 1950, the FTC filed 31 complaints obtaining only 5 orders.6 In part, the law was weakened by the unintentional (?!) omission of asset acquisitions from the law; note that the law referred only to stock acquisitions.‘ Consequently, one legal detour was to consummate an acquisition via the purchase of assets rather than stock. Of course, this' alone weakened the law considerably. But the actual coup de grace was administered by the courts. In 1926 the Supreme Court held that the Federal Trade Commission had no jurisdiction in a ppppk acquisition, if the merging companies could exchange their shares before the Commission filed its complaint.7 A year later, the Court removed the possibility of the Commission ever ordering a merger to be undone after its consummation by declaring that only courts have such equity powers.8 In 193A, the emasculation of the law was completed by the Al Court's decision that FTC jurisdiction was lost even if the stock were converted into assets gfpep a Commission com— plaint, so long as the conversion took place before the cease—and—desist order!9 In addition, the standards of illegality adopted by the courts (and at times the Commis— sion) were such that the law was no more stringent than the Sherman-Act!lO The Agended Section 7 For twenty—nine years the FTC tried to have the asset loophole plugged. At least twenty bills failed to accom- plish this. It was for thirty—six years that this ineffec— tive piece of legislation remained untouched by Congressional hands. Finally, after a legislative process that can only cause one to look more favorably upon benevolent dictator— ships as the optimum form of government, the inadequate Section 7 was amended.ll The new law was based on the premise that industrial concentration was increasing with concomitant deleterious effects on our competitive system, and that the Sherman Act and Clayton Act were ineffective in deterring this. Since the asset loophole and the judicial standards of illegality seemed to be the central weaknesses in the old Section 7, Congress enacted this revision: . . . no corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other: share capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the Federal Trade 42 Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially.to lessen competE- tion or to tend to create a monopoly. 3 Note that the bill now included asset acquisitions. And, equally if not more important, the thrust of enforcement shifted from the relationship of the merging firms pp competitors to analysis of the markets affected by the merger. The Mechanics of Antimerger Enforcement ‘ Most antimerger cases are begun by the Antitrust W! Division of the Department of Justice or the Federal Trade fl Commission, both agencies having concurrent jurisdiction. f over this law. Private suits may also be filed, either for injunctive relief against an acquisition or to collect y treble damages if a private party believes itself monetarily I A injured as the result of an unlawful acquisition. Only i. those antimerger suits filed by the aforementioned govern— ! ment agencies are of concern in this study. Both of these government enforcement agencies contin— ually gather information which might point to unlawful acquisitions. And both are able to institute an inquiry into a merger-—either being proposed or already consummated—— should their leads indicate the possibility of a Section 7 Should an inquiry point to a likely Section 7 violation. —: i 43 violation, a formal complaint is filed against the acquisition. The complaint, of course, does not have the weight of a finding of law; it represents only a formal charge by an enforcement agency. The respondent may attempt to show that the facts as set forth in the complaint are either incorrect, or that the facts do not support the conclusion of law drawn in the complaint. A complaint by the Antitrust Division is filed in the appropriate district court. An FTC complaint is first heard by one of the Commission's hearing examiners who acts in an independent judicial capacity. If the initial decision of the trial judge or hearing examiner is contested by either party, it may be appealed. A district court opinion may be appealed by either party directly to the Supreme Court. An order of a hearing examiner may be appealed either by the respondent or by the Commission staff to the Commission level. An order of the Commission for the respondent is a terminal order. But a Commission order against the respondent may be taken to the court of appeals whose decision may in turn be appealed to the Supreme Court. The trial process may be eliminated or shortened through a consent settlement between the government and the respondent. The consent settlement might be reached before a formal trial or it might be reached during trial. In an Antitrust Division suit, the consent settlement must be AA approved by the court; the Commission must approve a consent settlement negotiated by FTC staff.lu Note too that both agencies have procedures for the advance clearance of mergers. :There is no statutory authority giving either agency the.power to.issue binding clearances but for practical purposes an advance, if granted, gives reasonable security against future govern- ment~prosecution. The Remedies The Federal Trade Commission receives its power to remedy unlawful acquisitions from Section 11 of the Clayton Act as amended, under which the Commission may issue orders . . . requiring such persons to cease and desist from such violations, and divest itself of the stock, or other such capital, or assets, held . . . contrary to the provisions of section 7. Section 15 of the same act affords district courts "jurisdiction to prevent and restrain violations of (Section 7)" and the Department of Justice the power to "institute proceedings in equity to prevent and restrain such violations."16 The Scope of Antimerger Relief The scope of remedial powers accorded the federal courts are broad, reinforced heavily by the Supreme Court's second duPont—GM decision, a decision concerned explicitly with merger relief. The Court held: *7— A5 Congress would not be deemed to have restricted the broad remedial powers of' courts of equity without explicit language doing so in terms, or some.other strong indication of intent. While the above decision represented clear precedent for broad judicial discretion in forming relief under Section 15, the Court did not then clarify the scope of relief available to the Federal Trade Commission in its anti- merger cases. Remember that in 1927 the Court had held that the FTC was without power to dissolve an unlawful acquisition; that such power was a judicial, not an administrative remedy.l8 But since that time there has been a definite judicial trend toward giving administrative agencies powers previously associated only with the judiciary. Presently Justice Stone's dissent in Kodak seems to be the law: in 1963 the Supreme Court assured the FTC of its broad remedial powers in Section 7 proceedings by stating: Congress in 1950 clearly intended to remove all question concerning the FTC'S remedial power over corporate acquisitions . . . It will be apparent from the relief orders to be examined that the opportunity to formulate relief in broad and varying fashion has not gone unnoticed or unused by those drafting such relief in antimerger cases. Guidelines for Antimerger Relief This broad discretion in formulating relief orders affords two opposing possibilities: relief might be A6 creatively and conscientiously drafted or relief might become an economic lacuna. Recognizing the danger of offering such broad discretion, the Supreme Court has suggested.some rather efficacious guidelines: 1. The relief available is still a question mark. appears that treble damage Section 7, they can not be deterrence to mergers. Since the Clayton Act is a civil statute, relief decrees are not to be punitive. "Courts are not authorized in civil proceedings to punish anti- trustnyiolators, and relief must not be puni- tive. But economic hardship is not to thwart effective relief for the central issue is the elimination of a potential or actual restraint of trade. "Those who violate the Act may not reap the benefit of their violations and avoid an undoing of their unlawful projecg on the plea of hard- ship and inconvenience." 2 In Spite of the breadth of relief powers, divestiture is to be the prime remedy in anti— merger cases. "(Divestiture) is simple, relatively easy to administer, and sure. It» should always be in the forefront of-a court's mind whep a violation of Section 7 has been found."2 And the government is to have the benefit of the doubt in relief formulations. "(Since) the suit has been a futile exercise if the government proves a violation but fails to secure a remedy adequate to redress it . . . once the government has successfully borne the considerable burden of establishing a violation of law, all doubts as to the remedy are to be resolved in its favor." in private treble damage suits Suffice it to say that, while it suits are available under relied upon as a source of 26 ___l *- —__. _. . _ ———_—._ _ -.—-.-._—.-_«_. A7 The Standards of Enforcement The determining of guilt or innocence under the new- Section 7 centers around the relevant market affected by the merger. This is logical since the law is concerned’ with anticompetitive effects in some line of cemmerce in some section of the country. Any "substantial" lessening- of competition can be determined only in terms of some relevant market. The Determination of-a Relevant Market In its first Celler-Kefauver case, the.Supreme Court came to grips with the relevant market question and settled the differences between its broader.duPontecellophane standard of "reasonable interchangeability" and its narrower duPont—GM standard of "peculiar characteristics and uses."27 Had the Court adopted the former standard, relevant markets for Section 7 purposes would be much broader in their scope, and acquisitions in such markets would not as likely be found in violation of the law. But in Brown Shoe the Court Opted for the "peculiar characteristics" test and in so doing strengthened the government's hand in antimerger enforcement.2 ReSpondents clearly were not to be able to circumvent the law by claiming the range of products com- posing their industry to be so wide that their particular merger would have only an imperceptible effect on compe- tition. A8 Two years later the Court added an important footnote to the above. Section 7 was not to be limited "to compe- tition between identical products"; just because the. competition . . may be called "inter—industry compe— tition" and is between.products with distinctive characteristics does not auto- matically pemove it from the reach of Section 7. 7 Respondents clearly were not to be able to circumvent the law by so narrowly drawing relevant markets as to show no competitive overlap between their products. Respondents cannot evade the law by showing pppgd product markets and arguing that their merger is of small consequence given the breadth of the market; nor can they evade the law by showing narrow product markets and arguing that their merger does not involve the union of competing products. Given the recent posture of the courts, one can conclude, therefore, that the government will have consid- erable discretion in selectingthatrelevant market which best suits its purposes for indicating anticompetitive effects. And the courts, particularly the Supreme Court, is likely to require a most persuasive presentation by respondent's counsel before rejecting the government's rele— vant market. As one would expect, this inclination of the judiciary has not gone without notice and critical comment.3O A9 The Structure of the Relevant Market After the relevant market has been determined, the central thrust of antimerger analysis focuses on the structure of that market and the-impact of the merger in question upon that structure. As the Court said in Brown Shoe: The market share which.companies may control by merging is one of the most important~ factors to be considered when determining the probable effects of the combination on- effectige competition in the relevant market. and in Philadelphia National Bank: Specifically we think that a merger which. produces a firm controlling an undue percent- age share of the relevant market, or results in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market, is so inherently likely to lessen competition substantially that it must be enjoined in the absence of evidence showing that the merger is not likely to have anti—competitive effects. ~ In the latter decision quoted, the Supreme Court reviewed a bank merger which yielded the merging banks over thirty percent of the market and resulted in the largest two banks holding over fifty percent of that market. Mainly on the basis of these percentages, the Court drew the conclusion that this merger would violate Section 7, and in so doing established a benchmark: that in the absence of mitigating circumstances, any percentages of this magnitude would be proof of a violation.33' Since that time, the Court has indicated that the percentage benchmarks can be much smaller and still 5O constitute a violation. In a market.experiencing many acquisitions, a merger of the third and sixth largest firms resulting in a combined market share of less than ten percent of the relevant market was-sufficient.to condemn the merger under Section 7.3Ll Less than a.month later the Court strongly reaffirmed this position, holding that in. another industry displaying a trend.towards.greater con— centration, the acquisition by the tenth of the eighteenth largest producer, which resulted in a national market share of only four and a half percent, was not permissible under the standards of Section 7.35 This emphasis of the.judiciary-on the structure of the relevant market, particularly the market shares and the historical trend of concentration in that market,-is of signal importance. It indicates an acceptance-by the Court of the hypothesis, grounded in economic theory, that while competition may be a function of several factors, it is most definitely a function of the number and size distri— bution of the firms in the market; that without a competi— tive market structure, the benefits of competition cannot be expected. The Court's hostility towards advancing concentration in-markets brought under its Section 7 scrutiny clearly indicates that the judiciary and the Commission are strongly influenced by the purported Congressional intent . . to arrest the trend toward concentration, the tendency to monopoly, before the consumers alternatives disappeared through merger . 6 51 Additional Standards of Enforcement As if to emphasize that the enforcement of the new Section was to stick to.a ppructurgl approach and not become bogged down in the swamp of intent, conduct and: performance standards, a key lower court judgment held: If the merger offends the statute in any relevant market then good motives and even demonstrable benefits are irrelevant and afford no defense. To further-strengthen-the government's hand in prosecuting Celler-Kefauver cases, the Supreme Court emphasized that-the burden of proving an actual substantial lessening of competition is not to be placed upon the government agency filing the complaint. w Congress used the words "may be substantially It; to lessencompetition," to indicate that its p . concern was with probabilities, not certain- V ties . . .-Mergers with a probable anticom- petigéve effect were to be proscribed by this- A Act. '* The Court has emphasized that the law is to apply to w' all types of corporate marriages since one reason for Celler-Kefauver was. 4 . . to bring the entire range of corporate i amalgamations from pure stock acquisitions - to pure assetpgacquisitions within the SCOpe ! of Section 7. r and applies . . . not only to mergers between actual competitors, but also to vertical and fl conglomerate mergers whose effect may tend l to lessen competition . 52 Finally, apart from the actual anticompetitive conse- quences predicted from structural analyses, the Supreme Court has explicitly and without qualification recognized in the law a social preference for internal growth. In Philadelphia National Bank we find that . osurely one premise of an antimerger statute such as Section 7 is that corporate growth by internal expansion is socially preferable to growth by acqu1s1tion. Conclusion Celler-Kefauver enforcement has followed a struc— tural thrust. Questions about market shares, vertical integration, concentration, elimination of competitors, and product differentiation have been in the forefront as key criteria. Supplementing these structural criteria, close.attention has been paid to anticompetitive practices .3 made ppssible by the market's structure. Such practices as reciprocity, vertical leverage, and deep-pocket leverage, '1 made possible by the structure of a market and their use made more likely by mergers within the market, have been i influential factors in damning some acquisitions. A i As Book has so well summed it up: . following the lead of the Supreme Court, the Commission and the lower courts (are) increasingly focusing on the question of where and how competition might be lessened as the, result of an acquisition as they, in effect, inquired over and over: who can get hurt, l where, how and how much? 2 ! 53 FOOTNOTES CHAPTER II 138 Stat. 731 (191A). 2U.- S., CongressionalRecord, 51:1A, p. 138A8, quoted in David D. Martin, Mergers and fHe Clayton Act (Berkeley: Univ. of Calif. Press, 1959), p. AA. 3A legislative history of the original Section 7 can be found in Martin, ibid., chap. 2. A See for example: WilliamA. Carter, "The Clayton Act, Original Section 7: Re-examination and Reappraisal," Antitrust Bulletin, 8 (March-April, 1963), pp. 187—225. 5Martin, op. cit., pp. 205 and 201. 6Martin,-ibid., p. 1A9. 7Thatcher Mfg. Co. v. FTC, 272 U. S. 55A (1926). 8FTC v. Eastman Kodak Co., 27A U. S. 619 (1927). 9Arrow-Hart & Hegeman Electric Co. v. FTC, 291 U. S. 587 (193"). 10Martin, op. cit., pp. l35-1A6. 116A Stat. 1125 (1950). 12Legislative histories of amended Section 7 can be. found in: Martin, op. cit., chap. 7; "Note, Section 7 of the Clayton Act: A Legislative History," Columbia Law, Review, 52 (June, 1952), pp. 766-781; Charles F. Phillips, Jr. and George R. Hall, "Economic-and Legal Aspects of Merger Litigation, 1951-1962," Univ. of Houston Bus1ness Review, 10 (Fall, 1963), chap. II; MiltonHandler and Stanley D. Robinson, "A Decade of Adminlstratlon-of the Celler—Kefauver Antimerger Act," Columbia Law Rev1ew, 61 (April, 1961), pp. 652—678; Brown Shoe Co. v. U. S., 370 U. S. 294 at 311-323 (1962). 136A Stat. 1125 (1950). r—fl' —~. ”._.—._. ._.. .,. 5A 1"For outlines of Section 7 enforcement mechanics, see: Betty Bock, Mergers and Markets (3rd ed.; New York: The National Industrial Conference Board, July, 196A), pp. 6—10; "Aspects of Divestiture as an Antitrust Remedy- Comment," Fordham Law Review, 32 (October, 1963), pp.l39- 1A2; "Government Agency Profile-—the FTC," Mer ers & Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Spring, 1966), pp. 76-78. 1538 Stat. 73A (191A), 15 U.S.c. 21 (196A). l61b1d. 17U.S. v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 316 at 328 (1961); see also International Salt Co. v. U. S., 332 U.S. 392 at AOO-AOI (19A75. l8FTC v. Eastmaanodak, loc. cit. 19For a tracing of this trend, see: Michael Stepanek, "Implied Powers of Federal Agencies to Order Divestiture," Notre Dame Lawyer, 3A (August, 196A), pp. 581— 593. 2OU.S. v. Philadelphia National Bank, 37A U.S. 321 at 3A8 (196377 ZlULS. v. duPont, op. cit., p. 326. (lguu)22gp§. v. Crescent Amusement Co., 323 U.S. 173 at 189 23Divestiture requires the defendants to sell certain properties, securities or assets; dissolution requires the separation of a business into two (or more) parts; divorce— ment is the result of divestiture. These three terms, the "three D's" of antitrust enforcement, are for practical pur— poses'synonomous. In this study, the term "divestiture” will-predominate. 2”U.S. v. duPont, op. cit., p. 331. 2516101. at 323 and 33A. 26Thomas F. Daly, "Current Trends in Relief Under Clayton Act Section 7," Dickinson Law Review, 70 (Fall, 1965), pp. 6—10; ”Note, Availability of Divestiture in Private Litigation as a Remedy for Violation of Section 7," Minnesota Law Review, A9 (December, 196A), pp. 267-283; "Analysis, Treble Damages Under Section 7 of the Clayton Act,” BNA Antitrust & Trade Regulation Report, No. 227, p. B-l. 55 27Of. U.S. v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377 at 395 (1956) with U.S. v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586 at 593—9A (1957). 28Brown Shoe Co. v. U;§., op. cit., pp. 325—326. Brown also served to affirm this test as used in two key lower court government victories: ULS. v. Bethlehem Steel Cor ., 168 F. Supp. 576 (1958) and Crown Zellerbach v. FTC, 29 F. 2d 800 (1961), cert. denied 370 U.S. 937 31962). 29U.S. v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. AAl at A52-53 (196A). In this case the competing products with distinctive characteristics were glass and metal containers. 30See Paul W. Cook, "Merger Law and Big Business: A Look Ahead," New York University Law Review, A0 (October, 1965), pp. 710-72A and Milton Handler, "Mergers" in "Recent Antitrust Developments," Michigan Law Review, 63 (November, 196A), pp. 67—78. 31Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., op. cit., p. 3A3. 32U;§. v. Philadelphia National Bank, Qp. cit., p. 363. 331919., pp. 364-365. 3MQLS. v. Von's Grocery Co., 38A U.S. 270 (1966). 35pps. v. Pabst Brewing Co., 38A U.S. 5A6 (1966). 36U.S. v. Philadelphia National Bank, op, cit., p. 367; see also Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., op. cit., pp. 301 and 332. 37U.S. v. Bethlehem Steel Corp., pp. cit., p. 617. 38Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., op. cit., p. 323. 39U.S. v. Philadelphia National Bank, op. cit., p. 3A2. uoBrown Shoe Co. v. U.S., op. cit., p. 317. “1U.S. v. Philadelphia National Bank, op. cit., p. 370. "2Betty Bock, op. cit., p. 89. CHAPTER III THE EFFECTIVENESS OF CELLER—KEFAUVER RELIEF After more than a decade of case by case interpretation, section 7 has proved a very potent weapon against concentration.l' The Theory of Effective Relief The legal standards of Celler-Kefauver enforcement have been essentially structural in their thrust as was indicated in the last chapter. This has important impli— cations for the type of relief which should follow anti— merger cases. For once the structural standard is accepted as the proper method of predicting the anticompetitive effects of an acquisition, the type of relief required for violations of this standard is thereby determined. The structural enforcement standard requires struc- tural relief; indeed it could not be otherwise. Adopting the structural standard means that an anticompetitive acqui— sition is not condemned because of the "intent” of those making the acquisition; nor is it condemned because of some demonstrated or predicted impact on the firms' performance. It is condemned because the acquisition will (or is likely t0) afford the acquiring firm additional market power through its controlling a larger share of a particular market or its gaining the ability to exert leverage in other 56 57 markets. Since the offense stems from a change in the structure of a market, the relief must endeavor to change. that structure. Whenever an anticompetitive increment in market power is attained by the-merger route, structural relief requires. the restoration of the acquired firm through a divestiture order. Only this sort of relief strikes at the very. structure of the markets involved. Injunctive-relief, i.e. some form of order directing the acquiring firm to behave as if it did not gain this market power, is clearly unaccept— able. Indeed placing such a regulatory role on the govern— ment is repugnant to the whole concept of antitrust. Equally repugnant would be to do nothing—~to allow the increased market power to remain untouched. To-repeat: if all markets prior to an anticompetitive acquisition were, by structural standards, workably competitive and subsequent to the acquisition are not, these standards require divesti— ture of the acquired firm so that the markets affected are returned to their premerger, workably competitive status. But disgorging the acquired firm from its acquirer is only a necessary, not a sufficient condition, for enacting effective relief. Along with re—establishing the acquired firm, it is also necessary that this "new" firm be made viable; a mere shadow of its former self is not acceptable. Indeed, re-establishing 'new" firms that are unable to stand on their own would make any relief efforts farcical. 58 A theory of effective antimerger relief would enable one to predict whether the harmful effects of an acquisition would in fact be null and void, post—relief. When the acquired firm is re—established as an independent, viable firm such a prediction can be made. A pure theory of effective relief might add a third condition to the above. As long as an anticompetitive acquisition remains consummated, the incremental market power can be used by the acquiring firm. Consequently, effective relief is also a function of the time required to re-establish the independent, viable firm. The quicker the independence and Viability relief criteria are met in a given anticompetitive acquisition, the more satisfactory is the relief. Relief which immediately re—established the acquired firm as a viable independent without its acquirer ever having the opportunity to exert his newly-gained market power would be effective relief in its purest form. Of, course stopping an anticompetitive acquisition before consummation would be an example of relief par excellence. The Methodology of Pure Relief If the effectiveness of relief is predicted from these three factors—~independence, viability and time——the method— ology of a study of the effectiveness of relief under the Celler—Kefauver antimerger law would seem quite simple. A random sample of successful government antimerger cases would be selected, analyzed and the relief judged effective 59 if the acquired firm were now operating again, if it were viable, and.if the acquiring firm.were unable to exert its incremental market power for any significant time period. The test of independence would require-that the "new" firm be rechartered as a "new” corporation,.free of all interlocking directorates, financial ties and-managerial relations with its_former parent, and not.engaged in collusion with parent.or rivalsrvin short, that an.inde— pendent center of initiative bere—estab’l‘i'Shed.2 The Test of Survival The viability of the.new firm can best be tested by its survival. An inefficient or noneviableifirm_simply will not-survive. In-the long run, survival or death is« its own measure. In-the short run, profits are.an indi— cator of survival. Without profits a firm will eventually fail, for.barring subsidization, firms cannot long operate, at a loss. Testing viability.by survival avoids the obvious pit— falls of the interview method in-evaluating a firm's-via— bility as well as the numerous difficulties found in Judging viability by some sort of optimum size method based 3 on engineering or accounting data. Instead the profit-of the "new" firm would be considered as the indicator of its viability.Ll Testing viability by survival avoids the possible, error of predicting satisfactory relief solely from the Wm“). ‘7‘-” r1— . ‘ . : -4...2.: ‘ ‘ t v IIIIIIIIIIIII7________________________——r7 60 H H observation that the new firm has been restored-to its "original" condition. Actually, restoration which only mirrored the firm at the time of its acquisition could be far from satisfactory. For if the acquisition had been consummated some time prior to the structural relief, the "new" firm, restored to its "original" condition, would likely be an outmoded one, either in a technological or marketing sense. Such a defective restoration would soon manifest itself in unsatisfactory profits and probable failure. Similarly, the survival criterion requires that the parent divest all the key elements of its acquisition. For retaining important assets or personnel would result in "new" firm. unsatisfactory profit levels for the There are some procedural problems in the methods ology with respect to viability. How large must profits be to constitute a viable firm? How long must the firm survive to be considered viable? Observers might differ on the margins and time span they considered acceptable. In general, the trend of profits is a better indicator of viability than some specific level of profit. If a re— established firm has been in existence for five years with declining profit levels each year and now earns less than government bonds, relief has failed. If profit levels are increasing or remain steady at a rate above this bond rate for five years, this indicates the relief has been —: r 61 successful by the Viability criterion. Five years from the date of restoration seems to be a reasonable time period to expect survival. A business failure after this time will probably be due to factors other than weaknesses in the relief decree. How long can an acquisition remain consummated prior to the unraveling, and still have the relief be judged successful? A purist might argue: no more than one year. Those working in antitrust, for whom the vagaries and delays of antimerger enforcement are closer to home, might argue to the other extreme: if the independence and viability criteria are met, the relief has been successful. The Methodology Reiected It would seem the methodology for such a study would flow neatly from the theory of relief. Since effective relief is predicted from observing three phenomena——inde— pendence, viability and time—-one would only have to take a particular case, ascertain if the acquired firm is now back in business for itself; if_so, study the trend or level of its profits since restoration; and, if a purist, consider how long the acquired firm remained under its parent's tutelage before the state revoked the right of custody. Those familiar with research in antitrust realize that the field seldom lends itself to such neat research patterns. And, alas, antimerger relief is no exception to 62. this general rule. As it turns out, relief decrees seldom result-in-truly independent firms. And without independent firms, and their profit statements, there can be no easy survival tests. Consequently, a study adhering to pure relief standards would find almost all relief orders unsatis— factory--since the first-criterion would not be met via thev re—establishment of an independent center of initiative. As,a result, survival data, in fact not even available, would not apply to an independent firm. This leaves only the third, and probably least important, criterion for which data are available: the time period during which the acquisition remained consummated. The Methodology of This Study Since the main concern in the relief problem is the fate of the acquired assets, and since, as it turns out, this fate takes on different forms and shapes in almost every relief order, the data seem to dictate a case-by-case' approach. There are two pitfalls to avoid in using this- approach. The repetition of cases can make for dull reading. And the emphasis on description presents the risk of excluding a central analysis to draw the cases together. To avoid the first pitfall the actual case descriptions have been confined to an appendix, Appendix A, easily accessible to the interested reader but as easily avoided by others. And to draw the cases together,a continuum of - _ ...._..._ . .. ._.___..,____.._ ._.—nu” J.- 63 relief has been developed to give an overview of antimerger relief. The cases to be examined will be dropped into the- categories on the continuum; the criteria which determine placement on the continuum are the centralizing influences tying the cases together. The Sample The sample of merger cases to be evaluated is drawn from the universe of all amended Section 7 cases filed by the government since the law's inception through the calendar year 1960, which have been settled either by consent order or decided for the government by the end of calendar 1 year 196A. These cases can be found in Exhibit I at the end of this chapter. Eliminated from this group were the following: 1. those cases with "regulatory" aspects, i.e., any case dealing with the merger of banks, utilities or cooperatives 2. those cases for which sufficient data were not ‘h available to enable a classification. t The government had filed eighty—one antimerger cases by 1960. Forty—two of these were either still pending by 1965, were drOpped or settled for the defendant, or were eliminated because of data problems or regulatory aspects. Thirty-nine cases, then, constitute the sample. The Continuums These 39 cases have been placed on two four—category continuums. See Exhibits II and III. Exhibit II differs from Exhibit III in one important respect. In Exhibit 11, 6A only the criteria related to structure and viability are considered in the evaluation. If the relief took place X number of years after.the anticompetitive acquisition was consummated, no weight is given this factor in the construc- tion of Exhibit II. But in Exhibit III, the time required to attain- structural relief is taken into account in evaluating the samplecases. In a sense then, Exhibit III is for the purist. Including the third element of the tripartite relief criteria, the time span from acquisition to relief, will lower the classification of some cases. For example, the Owens-Illinois case, DEFICIENT by the relief standards of Exhibit II, becomes UNSUCCESSFUL in Exhibit III due to the-lengthy time the merger remained intact. Exhibit II The SUCCESSFUL Relief Category For a relief case to qualify for the SUCCESSFUL category, the acquired firm must be re-established as an independent firm, or the anticompetitive effects of the acquisition must be stopped in their incipiency so that no restoration is necessary. Since our concern here is with the source of control of a bundle of assets, the criteria for a SUCCESSFUL classification in an anticompetitive stock acquisition is similar: the stock must be divested in such a manner that the bundle of assets it represents is no 65 longer controlled by the acquirer nor sold to another purchaser_with similar anticompetitive effects. In this category one can sometimes obtain profit- and loss data to check on the viability of the divested. firm. But at times one has to rely on some other indicator of viability such as a Dun & Bradstreet rating of financial strength. What constitutes an independent purchaser? For the purposes of the SUCCESSFUL category,aapurchaser of the. divested firm, a-satisfactcry independent, must be some. individual, group, or corporation able to provide adequate financing and who (or which) has (have) no ties, either in a horizontal or vertical sense, with the industry of the firm being acquired in compliance with the relief order. The general principle for classification in this category. is that-a viable center of initiative be re-established- with no loss of-competition, actual or potential, in the process. I would add another requirement to this category which would deem certain divestiture orders as less than SUCCESSFUL- even though no loss of actual or potential competition can be shown. Certain conglomerate divestitures present the, case in point. In-a very real sense eyery SUCCESSFUL structural relief order results in'a conglomerate acquisition. For the restoration of'a once—acquired firm requires that someone 66 buyiand own the bundle of assets acquirediin the anticom- petitive~acquisition. 'Inrorder.togpurchaseflthist"new" firm, the purchaser must already have assets in some (assumedly) income—producing endeavor. .In the SUCCESSFUL category, the purchaser does not, by definition, have monetary interests in some.field related horizontally_or vertically to.the' "new" firm. Therefore the purchase will be a conglomerate one. But some would argue there is;a significant difference. between Individual X whose money is in,.say, paper.converting. buying a to—be—divested brewery and Corporation XYZ, one of the largest manufacturing corporations in the country (but! not engaged in brewing).buying the same.to—be—divested; brewery.. And some others would argue: 'there is no meaning— ful difference between the two purchasers since divestiture to either one would not affect competition inbrewing.5 I-am more impressed with the arguments against conglom— erate divestiture to "large" corporations—-particularly in the context of Section 7, a statute intended to arrest industrial concentration. There is actually not a great deal known about the impact on competition of large conglom— erate firms. But_until evidence is presented which indicates that-conglomerates do not possess leverage, sui generis, in this study divestitures to large conglomerates will be dropped into the SUFFICIENT category. 67 Brandeis' wisdom, as so often seems to be the case, still merits attention: Concentration of power has been shown to be dangerous in‘a democracy, even though that power may be used beneficently. For instance, on our public highways we put a limit on the size of an autotruck, no matter how well it is run. It may have the most skillful and considerate driver, but its more size may make it something which the community cannot tolerate, in view of the other uses of the highway and the danger inherent in its occupation t8 so large an extent by a single vehicle. How does one delineate between conglomerate divest- iture to the eligible independent of the SUCCESSFUL category and the ineligible conglomerate of the SUFFICIENT category? No easy answer can be given other than "by the size of the conglomerate." For example, any divestiture order which is met by restoring the acquired firm into the conglomerate folds of an occupant of Fortuneis tOp 200 manufacturing or top 50 merchandising firms would be SUFFICIENT. The SUFFICIENT Category In this category are placed those cases where the relief orders probably satisfy those charged-with-enforcing Section 7; only the purist would loudly clamor for more. Basically what drops a case from SUCCESSFUL to SUFFICIENT is a degree of difference in the independence criterion. The viability criterion for the restored firm is assumed to be the same for either category. But in the SUFFICIENT 68 category a true independent center of-initiative has not- been restored. Instead the unlawfully acquired firm has been divested in one of four ways: 1. sold to a "small" horizontal competitor 2. sold as a vertical acquisition but with no- foreclosure problems 3. sold as a market or product extension acquisition with no obvious loss of potential competition 4. sold as,a conglomerate acquisition-to a "very large-firm." There are obvious problems with the indefinite nature. of the above. What constitutes a "small" competitor? A vertical acquisition "with no foreclosure problems"? An W "obvious loss of potential competition"? Unfortunately no I quantitative answer.can be given to.these questions; for ' If example, one cannot classify all firms with assets of less # than X number of dollars as "small." These questions will have to be answered in the context of particular markets. A As a general guide, a "small" horizontal competitor ' would never be one of the ten largest, by_assets or sales, in a relevant geographical market. Absence of vertical foreclosure should, at a minimum, meet the requirement that- the acquirer has-less than-ten percent of the vertical market. No divestiture of a market or product extension variety is SUFFICIENT where the acquirer of the "restored" 69 firm has ever shown any intent of making such a move internally or is a sizable firm in the industry, financially capable of making such a move internally. The DEFICIENT Category This category essentially includes those cases with one "hole" in the relief decree. An example would be a series of anticompetitive acquisitions in which only a partial divestiture of the acquired firms was secured by the government;-or where the assets were sold in such manner that an obvious loss of potential-competition resulted. i Also included is a case where the structural relief borders H on SUFFICIENT but a complex marketing order, if enforced, H leaves a "hole" in the case condemning it to a lower rung.7 In short, the DEFICIENT category is basically for cases where the government secured structural relief, but where it was either not fully sufficient or the assets fell into less than desirable hands. Again, as in the previous two categories, viability of the "restored" firm is assumed for inclusion in this category. The UNSUCCESSFUL Relief Category The category of UNSUCCESSFUL cases includes the following: 1. no relief whatsoever 2. no structural relief, only a ban on future acquisitions 7O 3. insignificant or do minimus divestiture, not- striking at the heart of the restraint A. relief takes the form of a marketing order 5. relief is a combination of 3 and A 6. divestiture to a significant horizontal competitor vertical divestiture with foreclosure problems 7. 8. divestiture of a non—viable firm. In the DEFICIENT category, "partial divestiture" was mentioned; in this category the term "de minimus dives— titure" was used. What differentiates a full divestiture from a partial from a do minimus? Can a full divestiture be defined as a divestiture of 75 to 100 per cent of the r f anticompetitive acquisition, a-partial as 75 per cent or For the less, and do minimus as 10 per cent or less? —- —— 'I.....-— ._ _—___._H__._ : fi‘.“ present time this whole issue of what constitutes a satis- factory or unsatisfactory partial divestiture will be put ._--.- __ -_.-H.-.— off. This is not to diminish the importance of the issue. Indeed, the divestiture of only a "part," of only certain selected lines of commerce from an acquired firm, is a significant problem in antimerger relief. But its consider— ation has been deferred to Chapter IV where it can be placed in context with certain obstacles to effective relief. Suffice it to say at this point that there can be structural relief which does not fully strike at the restraint or else does so to an insignificant degree. 71 Conclusions from Exhibit II In a general sense, what conclusions can be drawn from the continuum in Exhibit II? The first observation is that relief is not an all black or white situation. There have been successful relief decrees; there have been failures; and some fall in between. But the next observation would probably be that of the predominance of UNSUCCESSFUL and DEFICIENT decrees. Of the 39 cases, a; relief orders are UNSUCCESSFUL and 8 DEFICIENT. Approximately three—fourths of the cases rank on the bottom two rungs. For those cases in the sample for which data are available, the FTC filed complaints against acquisitions totaling $665,927,000 (19 cases); the Department of Justice . filed complaints against acquisitions totaling $A66,028,000 A i (13 cases). A total of 1,131,955 dollars. ;. The total value of asSets divested in the FTC sample - y l E cases, again where the figures were available, was $128,809,000; the comparable figure for the Department of Justice was $199,085,000. A total of 327,89A,OOO dollars.8 i For those cases in the sample for which the data are available, the government issued complaints against acqui— sitions worth 1.13 billion dollars; 327.9 million dollars worth of assets were divested from this group. For the curious, this is a combined "batting average" of .290. 72 Exhibit III Turn now to Exhibit III. Remember that the time criterion now has been added as a further evaluative measure. Here those cases in which structural relief took at least three years to be enacted from the time of the acquisition have been dropped one rank from their classi— fication in Exhibit II and marked with a footnote "1." Those cases in which five years or more elapsed since the date of consummation to the date of dissolution have been dropped two categories and branded with the footnote "2.” Of course there were some cases already in the UNSUCCESSFUL category which would be further condemned by adding the time criteria——eight in all—-but there is no lower category inwhich todrop them. A glance at this Exhibit provides no gray area. The first three ranks of the continuum have been decimated, now holding less than one quarter of the cases. The last category is full to the brim. Of the four cases remaining in the SUCCESSFUL—SUFFICIENT categories, three involved acquisitions stopped in their incipiency before full consum— mation so no divestiture was actually necessary; the other was a stock acquisition. This points to the difficulty of unraveling acquisitions after their consummation. Average Time Spans The FTC cases in the sample had an average time of 19.0 months from the acquisition to the FTC's complaint. 73 For.those Commission cases which ended with some form of~ divestiture, the average duration from—acquisition~toi divestiture was 67.5 months! The Department of Justice fared somewhat better. For those cases in the sample, the average time span-from-the acquisition to the complaint-was 10.6 months., Where the- Antitrust Division secured some form of-divestiture in these cases, the average_period-from the acquisition to-the structural relief was 63.8 months! In short, for those cases represented on the contin— uums for which the government secured some structural relief, . the average number of months from the acquisition to the 9 divestiture was 66.0——or five and one-half years. Conclusion In this chapter the_goa1 was not to reach a conclusion- as such, but rather to present an evaluation of relief for a selected sample of antimerger cases. The data do indicate however that Section 7 relief, at least for this sample, could not be branded a glowing success by the criteria of the first continuum and could not be branded anything but a failure by the criteria of the second. The reasons behind relief failure will be eXplored in the following chapter. 7A FOOTNOTES CHAPTER III 1Thomas F. Daly, "Current Trends in Relief under Clayton Act Section 7," Dickinson Law Review, 70 (Fall, 1965), p. 2. 2The concept of independence will be considered again in Chapter IV. 3See Milton Friedman, Price Theor. (Chicago: Aldine Publishing Co., 1962), pp. l36-1A7; T. R. Saving, "Estimation of Optimum Size of Plant by the Survivor Technique," QJE, 75 (November, 1961), pp. 569—607; George J. Stigler, "The Economies of Scale," Journal of Law and Economics, 1 (October, 1958), pp. 5A—57. ”I am well aware of the problems involved in defining and measuring profit. However in a broad study of relief success in antimerger cases, the accounting profit would suffice to indicate a firm's viability. 5For good statements of the two divergent viewpoints, compare: Corwin D. Edwards, "Conglomerate Bigness as a Source of Power," Business Concentration and Price Policy, Conference of the Universities—National Bureau for Economic Research (Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press, 1955), pp. 331— 352 and George Stigler, "Mergers and Preventive Antitrust Policy," Univ. of Pennsylvania Law Review, 10A (November, 1955), pp. l78-18A. 6Louis D. Brandeis, The Curse of Bigness, ed. 0. K. Fraenkel (New York: The Viking Press, 1935), p. 80. 7The concept of the marketing order will be taken up later in Chapter IV. 8See Appendix B. 9See Appendix C for a breakdown on these figures. 75 EXHIBIT I Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Celler—Kefauver cases rought through 1960 and either won by the government or settled by consent by 1965. Year of Termination Case No.1 Year of Filing Defendant l7—DJ 1955 Schenley Industries 1957 18~DJ 1955 General Shoe Corp. (now Genesco) 1955 l9-DJ 1955 Hilton Hotels Corp. 1960 20—DJ2 1955 Minute Maid Corp. 1955 21—DJ 1955 Brown Shoe Co., Inc. 1962 22—DJ 1956 American Radiator' 1960 23—DJ 1956 Continental Can-Hazel Atlas 196A 25—DJ3 1956 Maryland & Virginia Milk 1960 26—DJ 1956 Owens—Illinois 1963 27—DJ 1956 Bethlehem Steel 1958 28—DJ3 1957 El Paso Natural Gas 196A 29—DJ 1958 Lucky Lager Brewing 1958 3l—DJ2 1958 National Alfalfa 1962 33-DJ 1958 Anheuser—Busch 1960 35—DJ 1959 Jerrold Electronics ‘ 1961 36—DJ 1959 Hertz Corp. 1960 38~DJ 1959 Diebcld, Inc. ' 1963 A2—DJ2 1959 National Homes Corp. 1962 113-111“ 1959 Standard 011 of Ohio 1960 A7—DJ 1960 Gamble—Skogmo 1960 A8—DJ 1960 Maremont Automotive 1960 52—DJ 1960 Ryder System, Inc. 1961 53—DJ 1960 American Cyanamid 196A 16—FTC 195A Crown Zellerbach Co. 1962 17—FTC 1955 Farm Journal 1956 lB—FTC 1955 Union Bag & Paper Corp. 1956 l9—FTC 1955 A.G. Spalding & Brothers 1962 21—FTC 1956 Scovill Mfg. CO. 1956 22-FTC 1956 Brillo Mfg. Co. 196A 23-FTC 1956 Scott Paper Co. 196A 25—FTC 1956 The Vendo Co. 1957 26—FTC 1956 National Dairy Products Corp. 1963 27—FTc2 1956 The Borden Co. 196A 30—FTC 1956 International Paper Co. 1957 3l—FTC 1956 Gulf Oil Corp. 1960 32—FTC 1957 Automatic Canteen Co. of America 1955 33—FTC 1957 Union Carbide Corp. 1963 3A—FTC 1957 National Sugar Refining Co. 1962 37-FTC 1957 Reynolds Metal CO. _ 1962 ”O—FTC 1958 Diamond Crystal Salt Co. 1960 A3—FTC2 1959 ABC Vending Corp. 196A AA—FTC 1960 Simpson Timber Co. 1962 “7-FTC 1960 Continental Baking Co. 1962 51—FTC 1960 Minnesota Mining & Mfg. Co. 1961 5A—FTC 1960 Hooker Chemical Corp. 1961 56—FTC 1960 Leslie Salt Co. 1961 lCase Numbers refer to those used in the Merger Case Digest of the American Bar gzgociation, Section of Antitrust Law, Revised Version, January 1, 196A, pp. 3-A and —270. \ 2These five cases were drOpped from the sample since sufficient relief data were not available to enable their classification on the continuums. 3These two cases, though won by the government at the Supreme Court level, were dropped from the sample for reasons outdined in the tax . u . This case, Standard Oil of Ohio, is included in the sample. Though ltldoes not represent a legal victory for the government as such, since the case was dismissed, Constitutes an economic victory since the dismissal was pursuant to a stipulation barring Sohio's Proposed acquisition of Leonard Refineries. 76 ooCo> honEHB comdfiflm HHH>oOm hwmwm ppoom moazonom hoczm proz moaozzom pCothmz nomad hXosq moflconpooam eaonoow hogwm HwQOprchoch HonEono Loxoom cowaflm Munoz Hfio made mocm Hwhocow HospSOh Spam oaonoflo Hopmmpo ocoEwHQ oaaflpm COOPCQO OHDGEO 93.4 3 ooflnpmo COHQD mHosHHHH mcozo apnea Hmcoapwz SSS nomnnoaflow czopv coo Hancocfipcoo wsflxmm Hopsocfipcoo UHEwcmzo cmOHpoE< 3 pawm oflaqu OEwoxmlmHDEdw mogm QZOLm zomdmlhomsozc< *HH BHmmem moEom HwQOprz mmawefi< Hoseapwz and: opscflz cooaom wQHUCo> om< .31. ll/ Lommm use mom SOHQD onno Mo HHO .Upm wcflwawaw hmmzm HmQOHuwz Hoopm Eofloacpom houwfluwm smoHLoE< 3 77 ooco> moofinpmo coasb thEwB QOmQEHm HHH>Oom Lodmm ppoom meadonom Loozm Hope: moflosmom mmHoQHHHH mcoso mmgflmm HmQOHuwz N222 onEopQS nomad mesq mpawm oHHmoq moHCOLpoon Ufioppoh nomom HMQOfipmchopsH HonEono poxoom QOpHHm mpmom Hno mass oozm flamenco HmQQSOh Egon UHoooflQ Hmummpo ocoeoflm mcowpaofiaom esono mzmo Hopsozflpcoo mwcflxmm Hancocflpcoo moosm Esopm oafiflhm Coousmo OHmeopz< mtaEfitho cmoHLoE< donaom Hzgmmooosmsb mweaeaodm mpwmsm HNQOHpmz acomsmupom3o5c< NLOpmflomm snowpoe< eoaaom eeoaoaoom .COflpHmfldwow %0 made hoped mgwoh ohoE Lo o>fih Umpomso we: eoflaoh HNQSQQJme soc: AoHQHmmOQ opoflzv mxcmp 03p UoQQOMU ommOIm .QOHpHmfisvow do opdb Song .o>flw cmflp mmoH use Amado» oohnp pmmoa we xOOp wowaop Handposhpm egos; xcwh oco condone owdona Modem w mom COHQD Oflzo mo HHQ .opm oEwoxmloHQEww Hoopm Eocofinpom uoeaom eqoaoaueom ooaaom Heuonoooom HHH BHmmem CHAPTER IV THE REASONS FOR INEFFECTIVE RELIEF Dissolution is not a solution; it is merely a delusion. Current events-are making this perfectly plain to everyone.1 A Short Prelude on the Relief Problem To find that the government has been unable to obtain effective relief in many of its antimerger cases is unlikely to surprise those acquainted with the history of the relief obtained in antimonopoly enforcement. To-them the recent lack of success could be plausibly explained as simply an extrapolation of an historical trend. Dewey stated that ". . . it is a commonplace in antitrust work that the govern— ment wins the opinions and the defendants win the decrees."2 While the former has not always been the case, for the government has suffered legal setbacks in the past, the latter position seems well documented. This inauspicious trend began with the government's first important Sherman Act "victory" in the Northern Securities case.3 The relief ordered was to dissolve the Northern Securities holding company and separate the Great Northern Railway Company from the Northern Pacific Railway Company. Commenting on the effect of this decree, the financier Hill is to have said: 78 79 Two certificates of stock are now issued instead of one; they are printed in dlfferent cglors, and that is the main difference. So it was the trend began. Seven years later-the Supreme Court specifically and~ fully approved dissolution decrees in both the oil and tobacco trustvcases.5 These decisions were much heralded coming at a time-when public antimonopoly feeling was. rather strong. President Taft said this about the tobacco decision: I venture to say that not in the history of American law has a decree more effective for such a purpose been entered by a court than that against the Tobacco Trustt Relative to past decrees, the President may have been correct but more perceptive men like Brandeis added: The decision was wholly unsatisfactory. Under the plan approved by the court the tobacco company Will-be in a better position than it was before the . . . suit . . . because it can do in the future under the. legal sanction of the decree, the things that had heretofore been considered in violation of the law° The reluctance of the Court to establish a sufficient number of new rivals and the resultant strong community of interest that remained in the industry made these decrees, as well as several that followed, nothing but paper tigers.8 So it was the trend continued. The courts' aversion to order structural relief has even affected, however subconsciously, its ability to find an antitrust violation--thereby neatly eliminating the 80 relief problem. Handler described one incident of this in his well-known TNEC monograph: Indeed, one cannot read the opinion in the Steel case without obtaining the firm impression that the Court's apprehension of the adverse effects of dissolution were in part responsible for its doubtful construc- tion and application of the law. The increase in antimonopoly activity which began shortly before World War 11 did not distinguish itself as a time of effective relief. Adams labeled the Justice Department victories of this time as "pyrrhic" because of the lack of meaningful relief.10 Goldberg found the same situation to prevail in his analysis of antitrust consent decrees.ll Verily, the powers that be have shown their preference for the industrial status quo. In those cases where the government antitrust attorneys have carefully prepared and adequately presented their case before the court, and the court responds with rulings in their favor, what explains the subsequent lack of efficacious relief? One causative factor is the general temperament or nature of the judiciary. Paying all due respect for property rights, they argue that structural relief . . . is not to be used indiscriminately, without regard to the type of violation or whether other effeiEive methods, less harsh, are available. Dissolution has been avoided since it is " . . . an 13 extraordinarily difficult and expensive undertaking." 81 One judge warned about proceeding with "surgical ruthless- ness" in relief orders.1u The courts' shyness to order effective relief cannot be totally attributed to a recalcitrant conservatism on the part of the judiciary. At least an equal measure can be attributed, bluntly speaking, to ignorance. When a judge tries a man for assault with a deadly weapon, generally the defendant's guilt or innocence can be clearly established. If guilty, the judge can be quite confident that the punishment he metes out will be acceptable, not to the defendant perhaps, but at least to the judge's peers. But when a judge tries a corporation for monopoly he is, in the first place, not so sure of rendering the correct verdict——and this uncertainty may cause him to hedge by formulating a weak relief decree. The blame for this latter characteristic of the judiciary rests with the government's antitrust people. For their function should include the education of the courts on relief. After a good presentation of its case in the second Shoe Machinery trial,15 Kaysen noted that the government's relief presentation which followed was . . . sketchy, poorly prepared, and failed to come to grips with any of the problems involved . . . (what was needed was) . . a fairly detailed plan, well—supported by evidence, not ten pages of generalizations and citations from legal authorities, supporteg by ten minutes of oral presen— tation.1 In a similar vein the government antitrust lawyers have been 82 reprimanded for concentrating their efforts on securing a “guilty" verdict and the "whateto—do-about—it—thereafter" has been relegated to the background.17 This can only serve to compound the problem. What does all this mean? First of all, it means that when someone says dissolution, divestiture and divorcement have ridden like the horsemen of the Apocalypse . . . leaving a medley of. headless, armless, and otherwi e dismem— bered business organizations,1 colorful though this may sound, it is also false. In the matter of antitrust relief, the more accurate maxim is: "What man-has illegally joined together, let no court put- asunder."19 As would be expected, the relief problem just described carries over into Celler-Kefauver enforcement along some rather familiar battle lines. On the one hand, the counsels supporting the complaint usually take the structural approach endeavoring to disgorge the acquired firm-from its acquirer. The counsels for the respondent, using the historical trend of judicial aversion to best advantage, submit briefs against-divestiture portraying it as "unduly harsh" or arguing that the "equities of this case favor an alternative remedy to divestiture." In the first merger-case brought under the amended law,lfluerespondent, appealing a divestiture order by the FTC Hearing Examiner, described that order as " . . . so impractical and 83 unreasonable as to be irrational, and so harsh and punitory as to be vindicative."2O Attempts to avoid a divestiture order do not stop at characterizing structural orders as "harsh;' "malevolent," "unreasonable,” or some.such synonym. Those formulating relief decrees are also reminded of various disastrous consequences which might-follow a divestiture order. In commenting.on a court order directing divestiture in the case of a bank acquisition, for example, the president of the acquiring bank warned that.the divest— iture of the new deposits might well cause "a run on the bank."21 How many public servants would like to run the risk of being held responsible for a run on a bank? The most famous merger divestiture trial of all, duPont—GM 11,22 was fraught with such tactics. The Court was beseeched to consider the impact of divestiture upon the stockholder, portrayed as an innocent bystander regarding his corporations' antitrust violation, who must be protected. from a complete divestiture order. One estimate placed the tax burden on duPont stockholders at $580,000,00023 and a decline in value of duPont and General Motors' stock of. twenty to thirty per cent was predicted if the government's 2“ In addition " . . . plan of divestiture were implemented. there would undoubtedly be a severe crippling of General Motors ability to raise new capital . . . (which) . . . could easily become so serious as to thwart or inhibit that company's future expansion . . . "25 And finally BA . . . I do not think it is over—alarmist to say that the entire securities market and even the entire economy might ulti- mately feel the depressing effects, and that the total adverse impact on the public interest might be so serious as to become a matter of genuine national concern. These arguments found friendly support in the law journals.27 Even from across the border this ominous prediction about the duPont stock divestiture sounded in Canada: It is clear that such a plan would result in millions of shares being dumped on the market in a few weeks time, which would probably lead to a market crash of 1929 proportions. The shareholders would thus be punished for a crime to which they were never parties. Furthermore, the two com- panies involved would find it very diffi— cult to raise capital needed for growth.2 In this "prelude" to the chapter, the general atmos- phere in which antitrust relief must breathe has been~ sampled. Those who feel the past is but a sample of the future would have predicted the case for securing effective relief under the 1950 antimerger law would be, prima facie, quite weak. Specific Problems.hiAntimerger Relief But the prelude above far from covers the "why" of ineffective relief. There are certain additional obstacles which have arisen in Section 7 enforcement which also deserve consideration. For the remainder of this chapter these barriers to effective relief, as found in recent antimerger cases, will be examined. Asset Restoration One of the greatest problems in relief is restoring the assets of a firm after they have been consumed by a merger——"unscrambling the eggs" as it is so often put. Whenever one firm absorbs another, even if their locations are geographically separate, the personnel remain separate and unchanged, and the assets involved continue in their general premerger usage, separating the two firms will present problems. At the minimum, certain financial functions will have been centralized such as the firm's billing or its payroll; more than likely, various marketing activities will have been coordinated or some centralized direction taken as to the dispersal of sales personnel or the shipment of goods. The promotional program might be combined or centrally developed. All of these present some obstacle to removing the acquired firm in one viable part. But the problems mentioned above are rather minor compared to those so often encountered trying to restore a once viable firm. In fact, in the hypothetical example just given, the obstacles are only procedural. In some cases the firm to be restored, quite literally, no longer exists. Probably the most unusual example of this situation involved an FTC Order directing the divestiture of the Dahl—Cro—Ma dairy in Hilo, Hawaii; before the order could be carried out the dairy was wiped out by a tidal wave!29 86 An Act of God is not always necessary to make a firm's restoration impossible; sometimes an act of manvwill suffice. In 1955 the leading agricultural magazine,.Farm Journal, acquired its principal rival, Country Gentleman. Essentially what was acquired was a subscription list and the right to solicit the substitution of Farm Journal for.unexpired Country Gentleman subscriptions. Most.of these solicitations were successful. A year.1ater when.the Federal Trade Commission adopted the decision of the Hearing Examiner's divestiture order, there was little.left to divest. .In the words of the Examiner: . . . as a practical matter divestiture of the subscribers! list now will.aecomplish -nothing. Respondent has,.by now, extracted all the juice from that.fruit as_well as from the list of current Country Gentleman advertisers. He then added, in language refreshing for a legal decision: .Country Gentleman is dead and the "assets" which it turned over to respondent are now without value to any newcomer or, indeed to any farm publication now in the field. When- his corn is taken from him and the horse dies, it is the height of vanity to strew the bare corncobs over his grave. All that- can be accomplished, then, is simple divestiture of the 2 trade names and the 2 lists, although . . . this at most may only- disturb, but will not diffuse the coalescence which has taken place. The FTC encountered a somewhat similar problem in the Diamond Alkali—Bessemer Limestone acquisition.32- In August of 1961 Diamond Alkali horizontally acquired Bessemer Limestone, a portland cement producer. The same year 87 Diamond closed down its own portland cement plant, the assets of which were sold and moved from Ohio to Florida. In-May of 1964 an FTC Hearing Examiner ordered divestiture of the Bessemer plant. But by then Diamond possessed but one portland cement plant——the Bessemer plant. A divestie ture order would, Diamond argued, eliminate Diamond as a producer of portland cement and merely substitute another owner of the Bessemer facilities.33 There seems no way to. fashion an order resulting in the premerger status of two portland cement producers though FTC counsel has suggested that-Diamond keep Bessemer for up to three years, build a new plant for itself, then sell the Bessemer plant.3u' In 1956, the FTC filed complaint against the Erie Sand & Gravel Co., holding three years later that Erie's acquisition of-its principal rival in the sale of lake sand, the Sandusky Division of the Kelley Island Company, violated Section 7.35 Erie appealed the case to the Circuit Court which remanded the case back to the Commission in 1961 for 36 But-by further study on the relevant market question. this time there was little point in the_Commission continuing_ the case. The acquisition consisted primarily of three vessels, dock space, and leases on dock space. One of the vessels was sold shortly after the acquisition; the other two were sold in 1961. All three found service outside the Erie relevant market. Faced with the impossibility of ordering Erie to re-establish another lake sand producer, 88 there was little the FTC could do but dismiss the case as "now in essence moot."37 The problem of asset restoration can become especially acute when the complaint is directed at a series of acqui- sitions. For example, the FTC looked askance on a series of acquisitionsixlthe dairy industry by Foremost Dairies, Inc.38 The complaint charged Foremost with violating Section 7 in a string of dairy acquisitions.* In a lengthy decision the Commission ordered the divestiture of the following ten dairies:39 Crescent Creamery Co., Sioux Falls, S. D. Moanalua Dairy Ltd., Honolulu, Hawaii Rico Ice Cream Co. Ltd., Honolulu, Hawaii Southern Maid, Inc., Bristol, Va. Welch Milk Co., Welch, W. Va. Banner Dairies, Inc., Abilene, Tex. Tennessee Dairies, Inc., Dallas, Tex. Phenix Dairies, Houston, Tex. Golden State Dairy, California Philadelphia Dairy Products, six states, northeast area. Divestiture of the three Texas facilities never took place since most of these assets were either disposed of or else combined with other Foremost operations in Texas. Divestiture here, like in Diamond Alkali, would eliminate Foremost from the Texas dairy market. Divestiture of the two Hawaiian facilities was also never accomplished. These facilities were combined with Foremost's into a new single plant operation which technol- ogically precluded corporate surgery. All that could possibly be accomplished by way of structural relief would 89 be re—establishing the two Hawaiian companies as dairy sales routes, dependent upon the Foremost plant for their produc- tion. This was rejected. Divestiture of the Virginia and W. Virginia properties was accomplished-—but even here the problem of unscrambling the eggs prevented a far from ideal relief situation. For in this case too there was substantial consolidation of the two acquired companies with existing Foremost plants.r The closing and consolidation process meant that the establish- ment of a new viable dairy and ice cream firm from the Foremost assets would leave Foremost as Virtually a corporate, shell in this market. So Foremost withdrew from the area. Thus, the divestiture did not increase the number of competitors. Foremost did divest itself of the Philadelphia dairy and the South Dakota dairy but was allowed to retain Golden State Dairy, the largest dairy in all of California at the time of its acquisition. The net effect of the relief order? Due to the unscrambling problem, the original divestiture order was met ggly in the case of two of the ten acquisitionstxabe divested. The FTC is not the only agency plagued with this sort of problem in formulating relief decrees. The Justice. Department filed suit against the 1958 acquisition of Blatz Brewing Co. by the Pabst Brewing Co. But in the meantime the Blatz operations were completely inosculated with 9O Pabst's and the acquired brewery dismantled.Ll0 Restoring Blatz, should a court so order, will require some imagination. The Schenley case, found in the Chapter III sample, also is illustrative of the restoration problem. This case, settled by consent, had no divestiture provision because Park & Tilford, under Schenley's stock control, had become a mere shell; its stock was of no value.All The Time Factor The one factor which works against asset restoration in all antimerger cases is the time factor. As a general. rule, one could safely say that the unscrambling problem is» a function of the time span from the time of the acquisition to the time of the relief order. The longer this span, the less likely are the chances for unscrambling. Industries which are especially dynamic, such as the dairy industry during these antimerger cases, present greater problems than those more constant in their production and marketing technology. The average time span in antimerger cases was discussed in Chapter III. These figures will not be repeated here. Suffice it to say that one could hardly expect to re—establish the premerger status in a market five or more years after the absorption took place. The longer the tumor remains in the body, the more difficult the surgery. 91 The Problem of the Partial Divestiture The problem of establishing a viable independent competitor often goes beyond the difficulties of unscrambling the eggs some time after the acquisition. The problem of physically extracting the acquired firm, it was just shown, can be a barrier to effective relief. Closely allied to this. is the problem of which assets should constitute the new firm. These problems are interrelated, but can differ in nature. The first was: Is it possible to disgorge a new firm? The problem to be covered in this section: If so, what assets do we disgorge? This problem can be best understood by following a hypothetical example. Firm A produces products X and Y. It acquires Firm B which produces products Y and Z. Assume all three products are sufficiently different so as to be in different relevant markets for Section 7 purposes. Thus, the only area of competitive overlap occurs in Product Y. If the acquisition violates Section 7 in market Y, the criteria of relief developed in Chapter III would require only the divestiture of the Y business, i.e., the re—estab— lishment of a viable independent firm producing Product Y. If only the divestiture of Y were ordered, this would be an example of a "partial divestiture." Defined roughly, partial divestiture is the divestiture of fewer assets or fewer product lines than acquired in an acquisition attacked by the government. Full divestiture then would be the 92 divestiture of a business as acquired——i.e., any and all product lines of the acquired company including those which, if purchased separately by the acquiring firm, would not violate Section 7. There have been many cases where the relief decree has ordered divestiture of less than what the-offending acquisition consisted of, in the way of assets and/or product lines. The partial divestiture is fairly common; and theoretically, as was explained above, there might be no objection to this. But in practice, the results of partial‘ divestitures have often been so defective as to indicate this sort of relief order should be avoided whenever-possible. A partial divestiture, since it consists of a "line of commerce" as opposed to the operations of a once—going business, generally is not conducive to re-establishing a viable independent firm. If, in the hypothetical example, Firm A is ordered to divest itself only of the assets used in producing Y, chances are that the set of potential purchasers of these assets will be other producers of Y who have the ability to purchase these assets and put them to use without "starting from scratch.” The true independent purchaser would have to buy this cluster of assets, quite possibly devoid of a home, and perhaps without even the human. capital which normally accompanies a full divestiture. All too often in the case of a partial divestiture, the assets to be divested make their way into the hands of unacceptable 93 purchasers——and very seldom into the hands of an independent purchaser. The relief-decree in the Hooker Chemical consent order directed such a partial divestiture.92This is one of the cases in the study sample. Hooker had purchased Durez Plastics & Chemicals, Inc., the largest producer of phenolic molding compounds, then purchased the phenolic molding assets of Monsanto Chemical Co. The consent order called for the divestiture of the machinery and equipment purchased from Monsanto. In-addition, an attempt was made by the FTC to enhance the possible success of this partial divestiture by ordering Hooker to aid the purchaser with engineering assistance, customer lists, and a six-months supply of lump resins at HOoker cost. But "mothering clauses" such as this are-poor substi- tutes for directing Hooker to divest a going phenolic molding compounds business of sufficient size and adequate personnel to enable its survival. In this case, the assets were parceled out to a small company with insufficient backing which droppedfrom the business. The phenolic molding machines? They're now in the hands of Union Carbide. Thus the Hooker acquisitions eliminated two phenolic.molding compound producers and the relief failed to re—establish even one of the independents. Gulf Oil's acquisition of Warren Petroleum also was settled by a consent order allowing Gulf to dole out several 94 packages of assets (roughly thirty per cent of.the Warren properties) to tendifferent~purchaser33437.On the—surface there-is-a prima facie caseethat such a relief order would be inadequate. In this case, it was.- -Warren Petroleum, as-a.medium size.independent-firm in the petroleum industry (at times.a thorn to the majors), has disappeared; W. K. Warren,;itsuable leader, now-sits on the board of Gulf. The partiaigdivestiture-enabled Gulf to retain key personnel whichlresulted;ianuif’s foothold in natural gas and its achieving an aboveeindustry-average, discovery rate for natural gas as well as~a most successful marketing-program in~natural gas.“l Of those assets divested, one petrochemical plant went to Jefferson Chemical Corporation, Inc., a firm fifty per cent owned by.Texaco. The cluster of assets which commanded the largest price in the divestiture order, oddly enough, a-group of tank cars which Gulf may have been glad to sell, went primarily to General American Transportation, one of the largest lessors of railroad cars (GATX buying. over 85 per cent of these cars9.. Almost half of these-were then leased back to Gulf.' The three butane gas properties' to be divested commanded the second largest price in the sale; they went to the Thermo-Gas Company which has since been acquired by MideAmerica Pipeline Co. The Midland Gasoline processing plant at Conroe, Texas, was purchased by Champlin-Oil & Refining Co., later absorbed by_the Celanese Corporation. 95 The remaining assets, less-the four per cent of the original Warren properties, went to small independents in the_petroleum-industry.~ No part of the order resulted in. another independent center of initiative being added to the petroleum industry to replace.Warren. Perhaps the extreme example of neatly carving out only.those assets of competitive overlap came in the Scovill consent settlement.u5' Among the general hook, pin, and eye: products produced by DeLong Hook & Eye, the acquired firm, were safety and common-pins.r Specifically these were the gnly notions also produced by Scovill. Hence, Scovill argued it should be able to retain all of the assets and personnel of DeLong, including its manufacturing plant, but divest those DeLong machines capable of producing common and safety pins and not use the DeLong plant in the future to produce such pins. The FTC bought their argument. Since the sale was-to be made in ninety days, it would be unlikely that anyone would or could purchase these pin machines-unless they were already in the.pin business and had a roof to put over them. Sure_enough the Star Pin Company bought the. handful of machines, the value of which amounted to less than five per cent of the purchase price of the DeLong. business. After the Scovill settlement the FTC fought a long legal battle with the Brillo Mfg. Co. (since acquired by» Purex Corp.) over its 1955 acquisition of Williams Co., a' 96 manufacturer of industrial steel wool.“6 Brillo was and is» a manufacturer of both industrial and household steel wool. Using the Scovill settlement as an example, Brillo's counsel was.able to convince the Commission that, since Scovill‘ could retain the DeLong.factory as lOng as it did not manu— facture the specified pins therein, Brillo should be able to retain the~Williams"factory as long as it refrained from producing induStrial steel wool therein-—since industrial steel wool was the only area of competitive overlap twixt Brillo and Williams“1l7 The-Commission agreed; their order of January, 1964, called for a partial divestiture limited to all the Williams' assets, customer lists, and trademarks but with the exception of the plant, machinery, and fixed assets.Ll8 As in the_case_of Scovill, this type of order almost precludes divestiture to anyone except those who already- have manufacturing facilities ready to handleethe Williams' business; i.e., the order in effect necessitates a horizontal divestiture to someone with excess steel wool production ready to take over the marketing function. This is what' happened. Partial divestiture has been ordered on the theory that the anticompetitive effects of the acquisition are eliminated if the acquiring firm does not use the acquired firm to produce products in the area of competitive overlap. But unfortunately, in practice, partial divestiture generally Mt ._ 97 seems to preclude the establishment of an independent firm. All too often, divesting only the assets of some line of commerce necessitates their sale in a horizontal manner. As-a result there is much to be said for establishing as a general relief principle the divestiture of all the' lines of commerce acquired in an acquisition which violates Section 7 in any particular line. The point is well taken- that; . . . preservation of competition dependS-on' the survival of.effective competitive units, not on isolated prflgucts in isolated geo- graphica1_markets. At least the burden of proof should rest upon the respondent to demonstrate that his proposed partial divestiture order will result in a viable independent company. For the respondent purchased a company, not a series of isolated lines of commerce any one of which can be readily divorced from the going concern. The test is whether the order is~ likely to.restore a viable firm producing in that relevant market where the violation was found. This test does not eliminate the possibility of partial divestiture——but practice indicates that disgorging the firm, as it once~ operated, better assures the chances of its viability and independence. Another disturbing aspect of partial divestiture bears mention. Not infrequently, a partial divestiture will be of de minimus proportions. Whether this is an intended or an unforeseen result is uncertain. At any rate de minimus 98 divestiture not only does not extract enough assets to establish the desired new entrant, it has no pro—competitive effect at all relative to the acquisition challenged-by the government.v Usually these settlements of de minimus propor- tions are found in consent decrees. For example, the Scovill divestiture mentioned earlier consisted of $47,000 worth of pin machines from an acquisi- tion costing almost $1.8 million. The Antitrusthivision, frowned upon Hertz’s acquisition of thirty-seven motor vehicle renting agencies costing approximately forty million. dollars. (Is there any doubt why Hertz is #1?) The complaint called for divestiture. Yet, in the 1960 consent settlement, Hertz was only to sell up to 1,000 of its 5,000 cars in the Miami area (it finally sold 162) and 900 of the 6,000 trucks it operates in the New York metrOpolitan area (which were sold'and then reverted to Hertz in.a bankruptcya case).50‘ Jacobs, the Hertz president, was indeed correct when he stated-the divestiture would have a "minimal effect“ on Hertz—earnings.51 Ryder System Inc., another motor vehicle leasing company, also was_b1essed with a,de minimus divestiture~ order after attaining the rank of number two in the truck leasing business——largely due to the merger route having acquired some 8700 trucks from 1955 to the time of the 52 antimerger complaint. The divestiture order called for the sale of four hundred trucks in total: 99 100 trucks to be sold in both Atlanta and Chicago 75 trucks to be sold in both Dallas and Nashville 50 trucks to be sold in Memphis. This was less than five per cent of the number mentioned in the complaint--and even at that Ryder completed only sixty per cent of the divestiture order in the year allotted for compliance. In August of-1962, the Chicago requirement was reduced to 60; in July of 1963, the Memphis_requirement was ”053 reduced to A Perhaps the extreme of de minimus.divestiture in a. consent settlement is found in the case of Diamond Crystal's 5“ Jefferson acquisition of Jefferson Island Salt Company. Island cost approximately $5 million. The divestiture of some."undevelopedV Seneca Lake property brought $A thousand from a local resident! This did little to establish another« salt producer!55 The Handling of Improvements So far, unscramblingand partial divestiture have been discussed as barriers to the asset restoration necessary for. effective relief. Still another-barrier has been the contro— versy over the disposal of post—acquisition improvements to the acquired company. The controversy, briefly expressed, is this: Assume Firm A acquires Firm B in violation of Section 7. Assume further that before or during the govern— ment suit Firm A adds substantial improvements to its B plant. Query: should (and there is the legal question of "can") the government order divestiture of Firm B with its improvements? 100 If the relief is to restore Firm B as it existed before the acquisition, then the improvements should not be included in the relief decree, some would argue. After all, they might add, if Firm B in its unimproved condition were sufficient to cause a Section 7 violation, divestiture of it sans improvements would be adequate relief.l Two points can be made in rebuttal to this line of reasoning. First, in a dynamic market the re-establishment of Firm B as it existed at the time of acquisition, some five or ten years later, may not make technological sense; restoration to premerger status might dictate an outmoded firm with no chance of survival. Second, it is logical to assume that if the Firm B had not been acquired, it would have added certain improvements itself; thus restoration of Firm B in a meaningful premerger sense requires that it be an improved Firm B that is re—established. In the first litigated decision which required divest- iture of a large firm, the FTC directed Crown—Zellerbach (hereafter Crown) to divest itself of the St. Helens' properties along with such improvements needed to insure the 56 viability of the new St. Helens. Since Crown had poured better than $14 million into St. Helens, it took the position that the Commission could require only the divestiture of 57 the original assets. In this case the Commission succeeded in obtaining the eventual divestiture of the improvements to St. Helens arguing that " . . . the broad purpose of the 101 statute cannot-be thwarted merely because respondent has- commingled its own assets with those of the acquired firm."58 The ninth circuit affirmed this order and Crown'so appeal to the Supreme Court was-denied.59 But the issue was far from settled by the Crown case and has crOpped up again. In the FTC's Reynolds case, the Commission ordered divestiture of the florist foil acqui- sition.found to violate Section 7 as-well as the building 60' Reynolds had built to house the company. At the time of the_acquisition the assets were housed in a leased building. But the Court of Appeals for Washington D. C. did not-agree¢ with the Commission's order in-toto: That-date (1956) marks the violation and on this record delimits the properties to be affected by the government's decree. After—7 acquired properties are not relevant, except in the case where they represent reinvestment of capital realized from the sale of property included in.a forbidden acquisition and- replacement of that property. 1 What are the implications of this line of reasoning? There are three, whichin certain situations, could preclude effective relief or nullify the intent of the law. First, as was mentioned before, divestiture of only the acquired assets, several years hence sans improvements, does not enhance a potential customer's view of the assets. In other words, who wants some aluminum foil machines without a. plant to house them? Apparently no one; even Litton Industries turned down the chance to buy them! The result in the Reynolds—Arrow case: no divestiture was ever accom- plished. 102 A second obvious ramification of this reasoning: carried to an extreme, it could prevent divestiture if the improvements were made in such a manner that they could not be separated from thevacquiredassets.62 And finally, barring the divestiture of post—acqui- sition improvements offers a firm an obvious way to enter a market externally in violation of-Section 7, extend the litigation process, in_the interim construct new facilities using the acquired knowehow, and then divest the-old acquired facilities at the appropriate time. Perhaps, by that time, they would be ready for abandonment anyway! To illustrate: Union Carbide desired to enter the polyethylene film business which they did in violation of Section 7 by acquiring Visking Corporation in 1956.63 Seven years later, the three Visking plants were dishon- orably discharged from Union's ownership. But in the mean- time Union built a new plant to produce polyethylene film which it retained——though it was clear that the new plant was an integral part of Union's Visking division. In a somewhat similar vein, the Antitrust Division's attack on Alcoa's acquisition of Cupples Products found Alcoa using the Cupples acquisition to enter a new geographic market.65 Having built a new fabricating plant in California after the unlawful acquisition, Alcoa balked at divesting this facility, arguing that it was neither a replacement nor an improvement to Cupples. Nor was its divestiture said 103 to be necessary to restore Cupples as a viable firm to its premerger condition since Cupples did not compete in the California market prior to its acquisition by Alcoa. But since Cupples had planned to expand into California prior to its being acquired, the Alcoa management took special precaution to avoid the divestiture of the Corona, Cali- fornia plant. As one Alcoa vice—president directed: . . . prudent business discretion required that the new and separate business facility to be built at the Corona site to be financed by Alcoa, not be brought within Cupples' ownership so as to subject it to the possibility of divestiture. Accord— ingly it was decided that the West Coast plant should be, and should be clearly6 identified as, the property of Alcoa. In short, allowingan Alcoa to keep a Cupples Corona plant would have the effect of permitting entry into a market thropgh an illegal merger.67 The Buyer Problem The relief problem does not end with the solution of "can we divest?" and "what-should be divest?" Then-follows: "To whpm do we divest?" This again is not a new problem in, antitrust relief.68 But the increase in divestiture orders due to the Celler—Kefauver Act has made it more common. What sort of buyer meets the relief criteria outlined in Chapter III? A buyer who will operate the divested firm successfully and independently. Unfortunately, like full employment and stable prices, these can be rather contra—l dictory. For the buyer who can generally assure success is 104 all too often one who does not meet the independence criterion, e.g., a buyer already established in the industry of the divested firm. In short, it can be tough to find a wealthy individual (or group) interested in taking on the uncertain financial support of a firm which has not been on its own / for some time in an industry in which the buyer does not already have financial or managerial ties. Our ideal buyer \ for divested assets would beziman in his middle forties, the possessor of substantial liquid wealth unlinked to corporate ties, having a sound knowledge of financial principles, a streak of business "maverick" in him, and the good sense to hire the most able of management to operate the divested facilities. These are stringent criteria. But the buyer criteria are-not so stringent as to preclude ideal divestiture. In the Spalding—Rawlings, National Sugar-Godchaux, and American Radiator-Mullins acquisitions, divestiture seems to meet these requirements to a "T." Independent firms were re—established, backed by money independent of the markets involved, and the firms stocked with adequate managerial talent. The Spalding divestiture probably best meets the standards for successful divestiture: the divested firm, the Rawlings Company, was purchased by a group of private investors headed by Burns, former president of RCA; the group then retained the managerial services of Carr, former presi- 6 dent of Rawlings. 105 Findinngny Buyer Why are there not more successful relief orders like Spalding, et_al.? In some cases divestiture fails when no buyer can be found. Diebold claimed it could find no one to repurchase its unlawful acquisition of Herring- Hall—Marvin and the divestiture order was dropped. Lucky Lager's acquisition of Fisher Brewing Company was allowed to stand in spite of a consent order to the contrary when- Lucky luckily could find no buyer. Maremont retained possession of Saco—Lowell when the divestiture order was.declared null and void after two years of . . bona fide and exhaustive efforts to carry out the divestiture provision . . . it appears that, notwithstanding such efforts, the diygstiture provision cannot be carried out.. In a similar vein the FTC rescinded its divestiture order against Reynolds foil machines when Reynolds wrote ". . . no_ prospective purchaser has even shown enough degree in interest . . . even to bring about the commencement of a negotiation regarding price."71 Reynolds, in a certainly novel line of argument, then proposed ". . . going out of business as an acceptable method of divestiture and one most likely to achieve the ends sought by the Commission . ."72 Though the Commission adopted Reynolds' proposal, it is not at all clear exactly how this type of order ". . . would enhance the competitive situation the Commission is desirous of main— taining in the florist foil industry."73 nr..._ __ r—___’ 106 In the Hertz, Ryder, Automatic Canteen, Borden, ABC Vending, Alcoa—Cupples and others (the list is not complete) the problem of finding a buyer-—any buyer——has hampered divestiture proceedings. Sometimes the problem takes on humorous implications. In trying to sell off several cigarette vendors, Automatic Canteen found the only inter- ested purchaser of its Louisville, Kentucky vendor was a rival who felt he could get the business cheaper if it were sold to someone else; he drove the purchaser out of business and then bought the assets in a bankruptcy pro- 7H ceeding! Finding the Right Buyer A different shade of the buyer problem occurs when a prospective purchaser is found but the purchaser is unsatis— factory-—usually for one of three reasons. First, a sale to the prospective purchaser may not alleviate the trade restraint found objectionable in the original acquisition. This would generally be the case if the divested assets were sold horizontally to an important rival of the divesting firm. This has occurred several times. The purchaser of the bulk of the Hazel—Atlas Glass Company, acquired by Continental Can in violation of Section 7, was the Brockway Glass Company, the fourth largest producer of glass products. Its purchase of Brockway cata— pulted it to number two in the glass industry.75 Had 107 Brockway been the original purchaser of Hazel-Atlas, this merger would have been a likely candidate for a Section 7 complaint! The sale by Crown of St. Helens to Boise Cascade could hardly be classified a rousing choice of buyer. Boise— Cascade had substantial timber holdings in the Pacific northwest and was committed to entering the paper industry on a large scale.76 Part of its growth has been via the merger route; by 1963 it advertised: "Paper Is Now Our Biggest Business."77 The opportunity to purchase the St. Helens property eliminated substantial potential entry on its own in the form of new capacity by Boise. A second factor which would make a buyer unsatis— factory occurs when the buyer is not truly independent of the divesting firm, or some tie would still exist between the divesting and the divested firms. An example would be helpful to illustrate this. Brown seemed reluctant to sever all ties with Kinney after the historic Supreme Court decision went against them. They pushed for a divestiture order which would allow the Kinney management to retain their stock in Brown arguing that preventing this " . . . would work an unnecessary hardship on innocent third parties who are presently in the Kinney organization and who own Brown stock.""8 In Union Carbide's first attempt to sell Visking, they developed a sales agreement which would have enabled 108 them to keep all but one of the Visking patents and divide sales territories between themselves and the purchaser.79 The Crown divestiture, which fell short on finding an acceptable buyer, also established rather close ties in production and marketing between Crown and Boise. Thus, in this case, the ill effects of an unsatisfactory buyer were compounded by a sales agreement which established ties. of mutual interest between the firms involved. For example the Agreement of Purchase and Sale, dated May 8, l963, between Crown and Boise allows Crown to continue operating one of the three paper machines at the St. Helens location until either 1969 or 1972 when it is to be taken over by Boise; Boise is to supply Crown with pulp for this machine; Crown will supply Boise with wood chips for five years; Crown will retain cutting rights on the St. Helens timber. for another five years; and Crown will sell about half of the paper produced by the two machines purchased by Boise for the first four years after the divestiture. This is all-done, according to Crown's president Sinclair, to ". . . protect the interests of the mills employees, the community of St. Helens, customers supplied by the mill and Crown Zellerbach stockholders."8O Not that any or all of these arrangements are per se wrong—-only that ties such-as these can become the type that bind. So far the problem of finding no buyer and the problem of finding an unsatisfactory buyer have been mentioned. 109 Briefly the reader might be reminded that a part of the unsatisfactory buyer problem is the non—viable buyer; i.e., the purchaser for the assets is found; he is inde- pendent of ties with the divesting firm and the relevant market involved, but shortly after the divestiture he fails. This happens with some frequency—-for example, in Hooker Chemical and Hertz. This failure could be due to the nature of the assets divested; at this time some of them are not always the mostmodern,particularly in cases where the divestiture occurred more than five years after the acqui- sition. Where does this line of thought lead? The buyer problem consists of finding an independent and likely—to—be— Viable purchaser. Often, however, no purchaser can be found or, if found, the purchaser is unsatisfactory. We now turn to the question: Why can a satisfactory purchaser not-be found every time? That the market for corporate control is imperfect is one plausible and highly probable reason. It is beyond the scope of this study to comment in any depth on this market. However, anyone who goes through the correspondence between a divesting firm (or its agent) and inquiring brokers and firms cannot help but be impressed at least by the sheer number of inquiries. Even as unlikely an asset as a salt plant in Utah drew 207 different inquiries. Prospective purchasers ran the gamut from a power boat company to a tourist lodge.81 110 At times, as was mentioned above, the package of assets being offered is insufficient to form a new firm or so outmoded as to be unattractive to any existing firm. Perfecting the market for corporate control would not, for example, have made Maremont's muffler manufacturing facilities less obsolete or put a roof over the Reynold’s foil'machines. In addition there is evidence of a certain (rather understandable) recalcitrance on the part of some sellers to comply with a divestiture order. It is beyond the scope of an economic study to prove bad faith on the part of some divesting firms. But some of the cases seem rather blatant. In one~case, letters such as this were not uncommon: I can understand Leslie Salt Company's reluctance to provide a prospective pur- chaser with the Plant Income Statements, especially if not doing so might result in, the plant not being sold during the period82. specified by the Federal Trade Commission. One unidentified telegram to Attorney General Kennedy contained this plea: "Continental Moving All Key Per— sonnel From Omar Plants in Order To Discourage Sale of Omar, Inc. Please Investigate."83 Union Carbide, when asked why it did not publicize the Visking plants it was to divest and in response to the implication that this might demonstrate a lack of effort on its part,rmw.this rather unique reply: "It would be imprac- tical because such advertising would only attract large numbers of curiosityeseekers hopelessly unqualified to purchase and operate the business."8M 111 This sort of strategy, if not evidence of a lack of effort to divest, does put Union in the position of being able to contact only those buyers it prefers to buy Visking. In other words, closely linked to the problem of the divesting firm being balky in its divestiture efforts, is the possibility of its.selecting a buyer it prefers to own the properties to be divested. As a general rule, having resolved itself that divest- iture is inevitable, it is in the divesting firm's interest to seek out or favor a buyer who will either be COOperative, phlegmatic in his rivalry, or destined to fail. It is in- the public's interest that the buyer be independent, a business maverick, and destined to succeed, as has been pointed out before. Consequently, effective antimerger relief requires that the authorities not give the companies involved free rein in-this selection. There is evidence that companies have attempted to_ select the buyer in their interest; this, of course, should not come as a surprise to anyone. Union Carbide presented Texaco, Socony, Continental Oil, then Celanese to the Commission as prospective purchasers of Visking. In the Crown case: Crown apparently pursued only Boise until we demanded that it open negotiations among potentials we selected from the total list~ it had furnished us of all personS‘wgo had made any inquiries about St. Helens. 5 112 An investigation by the FTC ". . . revealed what had been surmised: that Crown had discouraged negotiations with others . . ."86 One wealthy businessman, with no ties in the paper industry but with a reputation as an aggressive competitor, complained that Crown "had ignored his possible interest in purchasing St. Helens."87 In private correspondence with the author, concerning a case which must remain unidentified, one party close to the sale wrote: At the time that we were negotiating for the purchase of this plant, another . . . firm . . . was also interested . . . (the divesting firm) seemed to favor us as the buyer (since) the (other company) is known in the industry as a particularly destruc— tive element as far as prices arg concerned, and we were at least an unknown. 8 To recapitulate briefly, in this chapter, two main barriers to securing effective relief have been defined, explained, and illustrated with examples from actual cases. The measures necessary to effectuate the structural relief these obstacles at times prevent are reserved for the following chapter——though some policy implications probably seep from the discussion of the problems themselves. Two other barriers remain to be discussed in this chapter. The Marketing Order The marketing order was rather briefly mentioned in Chapter III. Its use has been common in antimerger enforcement. 113 The marketing order, as the term is used here, is a relief decree which directly involves the government in the determination of the firm's marketing mix. This is in- contrast to a pure divestiture order which leaves-the divesting firm free to follow its own post—divestiture course. Generally, a marketing order will dictate some aspect of a firm's price, product or customer selection policy for some period of years. For example, such an order might- direct_an integrated firm producing and converting Product X to sell 50 per cent of its output from its first stage to non—integrated converters at book cost plus 10 per cent for a period of five years; the rationale being that such an order assures the non-integrated converters of a source of supply for five years and prevents the integrated firm from supplying only its own converter, foreclosing the-others. Bluntly, then, marketing orders call for governmental regu— lation of some.part of the acquiring firm's marketing mix. To an extent, a ten- or twenty-year ban on future acquisitions without government approval meets the criteria of a marketing order. It-puts a restriction on the firm's marketing mix by cutting off a possible avenue of product or capacity expansion and involves the government's partici- pation in an external expansion decision. But in this section we are more concerned with the implications of marketing orders of-a different type or degree; i.e., there 114 are marketing orders and there are marketing orders. Those marketing orders which bring the government into price and customer selection policy in a direct and meaningful sense are the ones considered first. The orders containing a future ban on acquisitions will be taken up later. To begin with, it should be stressed that the marketing order is a deviation from the ideal of antitrust enforcement. The aspect which makes antitrust enforcement palatable to the libertarian is that the efforts by the government to enforce free markets supposedly will not involve the government in detailed regulation of markets. As Kahn in his excellent work on "Standards for Antitrust Policy" put it: "The anti— trust laws involve the Government in no entreprenurial activity.proper and require no detailed review of either basic investment or run-of—the-mill business decisions."89 Perhaps Kahn might have included the words "should not" before "involve." From a purely practical point of view, there is ample historical support for avoiding this sort of order. In the complex Hartford—Empire decree, where marketing orders were substituted for structural relief, the Supreme Court installed a complex regulatory scheme of compulsory patent licensing, "reasonable rates," and complicated credit arrangements. The scheme was.so complex, in fact, that all of the companies involved decided to form a committee to work out the difficulties among themselves!90 Such an arrangement is hardly conducive to independent rivalry! 115 In the motion picture industry Marcus tells us: The problems that arose.in connection with these judgments were, in the annals~ of the Antitrust Division, unique in number and complexity . . . Since l9A9, there has> been no time when the Division has not had ~several problems to wrestle with which have stemmed from the judgments. About two—. hundred sections of correspondence on the average of one and one-half inches in- thickness have been Spawned from the judgments. For one lengthy period, at' least one-third of the entire correspondence of the Antitrust Division was in the motion picture field. Amendments to the judgments; have exceeded the original*judgments in size. In number they have been legion. Back in 1940, when Wendell Berge headed the Antitrust Division, he complained that-the policing of such decrees was "highly difficult," that proof of non—compliance was "as difficult as proof of a new equity suit," and that often. lawyers can so skillfully guide the companies involved that they accomplish what they want "without technically violating the decree."92 Consequently, on both theoretical and pragmatic grounds, there is a strong prima facie case against marketing orders. The Court spoke wisely when it said: The object to be sought, for the convenience of the parties as well as the Court, is a. decree which will embody the necessary elements of suitable relief and require a minimum of sppervision by the Cogrt and reports and data by-the parties. 3 In spite of this, they are.often used in antitrust_ enforcement as a substitute, albeit an imperfect one, for structural relief. There still exists the attitude, even 116 among lawyers working for the government, that divestiture, is a harsh and radical remedy: better merely to substitute some injunctive order directing the respondent to behave in a certain way, subject to governmental scrutiny. Of course, this notion is false. Divestiture.is a conservative remedy since it eliminates the need for the close regulation of future marketing activities. Unfor- A tunately this line of reasoning falls on some deaf ears.9Ll What-has been the form of marketing orders in Section 7 cases? Some have been distressingly-complex. The American Cyanamid Final Judgment of August, 1962, involves more than ten pages of marketing orders too lengthy to, summarize here.95‘ They include such protective stipulations as enjoining American from increasing its production of melamine beyond thirty million pounds per year for a speci- fied time, various patent license clauses, and purchasing requirements. The court opens the door to becoming a regu— latory commission for American. Should American feel the price it pays for melamine it must buy from other producers is "oppressively high," it may petition the court which will (somehow) determine if the price is in fact "non-competitive." A meaningful administration of this.decree would seem to be a day-to-day job for someone with specialized skills in. chemistry, accounting, and patent law. In the Simpson Timber case, a consent order directing the marketing of redwood timber was entered in place of 117 96 This case is one of reeestablishing.theflacquired;firm. many which pointlup the supposed rationale of a marketing. order. The fourth largest seller of redwood lumber and- lumber.products acquired another substantial seller of the same product. In the consent decree negotiations, Simpson probably argued as follows:- "The primaryrestraint you are worried about is the possible foreclosure from the redwood timber market of non-integrated lumber product manufacturers with whom we compete horizontally and have sold lumber to vertically. To protect their supply of redwood lumber, we will agree to sell to them at reasonable prices 500,000,000 board feet of redwood timber over the next decade or so. This-assures them of a source of timber supply and the sticky problem of divestiture,is eliminated; we can all go home." To many, this line of reasoning must be appealing; at least it was to the powers that be in-this case. Thus Simpson presently is to sell not less than« 35,000,000 board feet of timber per year to a select list- of buyers until sometime in the 1970's at prices "less than $20.00 per thousand board feet for stumpage, plus 8% per. annum compounded from January 1, 1961, to cover actual carrying costs," plus the logging costs if done by Simpson. There are specific hazards to this decree-—which, in general, apply to all such orders. Who in Washington is going to see that the order is enforced? Is it left to the good faith of Simpson? This is the sort of decree which any 118 accountant and lawyer worth their timber could evade—-and that is no reflection on Simpson’s compliance. Finally, there is-a great risk, as will be pointed out shortly, in attempting to "peg" how a market~shouldeork‘several yearS' into the future—-which is what this decree attempts to do by allocating a certain portion of timber to a certain group of customers for a certain length of time at prices supposed to be reasonable both now and several years hence. As it turned out, thus far Simpson has so exceeded its‘ quota to the designated group that it is obvious that what it is directed to do in this part of the order would have been done voluntarily. Other examples of relief orders "pegging" what are supposed to be competitive market arrangements in lieu of- divestiture are: Prehler was to buy 22 per cent of the electriCal insulation-products it distributes from manu— facturers other than-MMM for five years; Diamond Crystal, in another-involved marketing order, must offer 30 per cent of the Louisiana rock salt from its acquired facility to- "all other producers of salt for sale who do not have resources and facilities for the production of Louisiana; Rock Salt" for a period of ten years in place of re—estab- lishing the company; International Paper can retain Long. Bell Corporation providing it sells A0 per-cent of the. output of a new paper and board mill (it was then building) to non-integrated wholesalers and converters for ten years 119 at "standard prices"; General Shoe avoided divestiture in part by agreeing to purchase a-certain percentage of the, shoes sold by iii distributors from other manufacturers; Georgia Pacific evaded divestiture by consenting to an order whereby it kept the Crossett Company but makes available 100,000 tonscfi‘coarse paper per year for five~ years to independent-jobbers and converters; then another~ five.years with a 75,000 per year quotas—all sold at a. price calculated by averaging the going delivered price of St. Regis Paper Co., Union BageCamp Paper Corp., Hudson- Pulp & Paper Corp., and International Paper Co.97 One FTC official-admitted that-such orders would require a "full- time staff_member to police." How do these orders "work out" in practice? Since many of them involve consent decrees,-that~question~isV difficult to answer, due to the paucity of data in these settlements. However, there are some limited data on the efficacy of these decrees. The data do not make a strong- case for the government's ability to predict "what the market should be like." In the Gulf-Warren.consent decree Gulf consented to- offer a certain portion of its LP gas to "independent non- major refiners" or "independent non—integrated petrochemical manufacturers." This was done to "protect" some firms-which were customers of Warren, to insure that they would continueI to be served. One of Warren's major customers of LP gas was. 120 Texas Butadiene and Chemical Company, one of the independents as defined by the order. In 1962, Texas was acquired by a subsidiary of the Sinclair Oil Corporation; all sales there— after to Texas, who still desired to purchase LP gas from Gulf’s Warren subsidiary, were now classified as sales to i a "major." In order to meet the established percentage : requirement, based on past sales which of course included Texas as an independent, Gulf would be forced to discontinue these sales, Texas forced to find a new source of supply. Gulf was unable to meet its percentage requirement of natural gas to independent refiners as directed in the order. Here again an-unforeseen factor in a dynamic market nullifies. what, if any, merit the percentage order had originally. Gulf,consented to sell a certain percentage of its-natural gas-to independent refiners. As in most all marketing orders of this type, the percentage was based on that handled by, the acquired firm prior to its acquisition7—then-extrapo— lated into the future as if there is some magic aura about that percentage to which the market should always conform. But some markets change, and the market for natural gasoline changed since the acquisition. Natural-gasoline sold to independent refiners was used as a blending agent, to increase the volatility of motor fuel. But since the octane requirements_of motor fuel increased during thism period, natural gasoline, with its low octane rating, fell into disfavor with independent refiners who switched over 121 to a high gravity condensate. Gulf, ordered to sell so much-natural gasoline to a certain class of customers,. found the bottom to have dropped out of the market.98 Another example of the inability to extrapolate from past market shares to what future market.shares "should be," occurred in-the-Lucky Lager order. Unable to divest Fisher Brewing Company in the allotted time, Lucky was permitted to retain the Fisher brewery. At the time of the acqui- sition, Lucky had 12 per cent of the Utah market; Fisher had 39 per cent of that market. Consequently, a rather unique, albeit illogical order was entered on the theory that the anticompetitive effects of the merger would somehow be nullified, if the two companies were not allowed to sell~ more than 39 per cent of the Utah beer market combined. However, Lucky found it could‘not continue to operate in the Utah market with this restriction; for financial reasons it_ would have to withdraw if the order were not altered. Luckily for Lucky, the percentage requirement was dropped- when its results became apparent. Recall the Brillo order of partial divestiture dis— cussed earlier.in the chapter; Brillo divested only the business but 393 the production assets of Williams which remained with Brillo providing they were not used to produce: industrial-steel wool. In-addition, this marketing order waspentered: 122 It is further ordered that from and-after the effective date of such divestiture, respondent shall refrain for a period of five years from selling industrial steel wool to customers of The Williams Company excepting that respondent may continue to sell industrial steel wool to any customer it served in common with-Williams - as ovauly 5, 1955, providing the maximum-unit annual quantity sold to each such common~ customer does not exceed the total unit quantity which respondent sold to it in the twelve months immediately preceding July 5, 1955.99. ‘ In other—words, if Brillo sold 1,000 units of industrial steel wool to a customer served by Williams in the twelve months preceding July, 1955, it could not sell more than; 1,000 units per year to this customer for five years there- after--and what it does sell must not be made on the Williams machines. Clearly, the order is designed to be protective. But even the best laid plans of mice and men . . and this order, as is the case with others, had to be changed. The Williams business went to the J.-H..Rhodes-Co. which found it was,unab1e to supply all of the old Williams' customers——which is understandable since the order did_not' enable Rhodes to purchase any extra steel wool machines. The old Williams customers were unable_to go to Brillo due to the marketing order; in addition, since the machines were not to be used to produce induStrial steel wool, Rhodes was unable to go to Brillo to purchase industrial steel wool to meet his customers needs. So, in 1965, the order was modi-, fied to allow Brillo to produce industrial steel wool in the Williams’ plant to supply Rhodes to in turn fill-his customers' orders. 123 The Future Ban There is another type of marketing order involving the government in considerably less decision making, but. due to its frequent and increasing usage, does merit attention. This marketing order is the order barring a firm from acquiring another firm (in a particular industry) without prior government approval for a.given period of years. In the sample of 39 cases drawn.for this study, 25 (or 64 per cent) had some form of future merger ban. All but two of the cases in the UNSUCCESSFUL category included some form of ban on future mergers without prior government approval. .What does the ban accomplish? First, it does not prevent all acquisitions by firms under the bane-only those not approved by the government. The government has approved some, though data are not available as to how many. The ban does n93, nor is it designed to, prevent any acquisitions in markets p93 specified under the ban.100 The question of what standards the government is-to use in approving the merger application of a firm under the ban is unanswered. If the standard is close to a per se ban (it is not at present per se), i.e., if it is next to impossible to secure government approval for a proposed acquisition in a market where a future ban exists, then in industries of heavy government antimerger activity (such as cement and dairy products) where several firms may be 12A operating under such a ban, the market for corporate assets may be diminished. On the other hand, if the standards applied in approving an acquisition are the same as those lapplied in any Section 7 proceeding (and there is some legal opinion that they cannot be otherwise), then the ban does no more than provide the government with a premerger notification process. Securing a limited premerger notification process may be admirable and desirable; but it is not admirable if the premerger notification is a quid pro quo for ineffective relief, i.e., if the government secures a future ban without prior approval in place of structural relief. Generally where the government has secured structural relief, the ban was not imposed. But in almost every case where no divestiture, partial divestiture, or some marketing order was imposed, the future ban is found. What is disturbing about the future ban is the impli— cation that it is a substitute for structural relief. In at least five Section 7 cases settled in 1966 the FTC imposed future_bans of five to ten years with no divestiture ordered.lOl This reminds one of Christ‘s admonition to the woman taken in adultery: "Neither do I condemn thee: Go, and sin no more."102 In spite of possible Biblical authority to the contrary, Elman correctly points out in his dissent in National Tea: 125 If National Tea's past_acquisitions were unlawful (as the Commission decision so held) because their likely effect, indi- vidually or cumulatively, was to lessen competition in any market, the public interest requires that divestiture be ordered . . .103 The Environment of Antimerger Enforcement That the economics of keeping markets free operates in a legal-political environment is a statement which probably surprises no one. To an economist working in-the area of antitrust, the term "political economy" is indeed~ a meaningful one, one close to home. Any enumeration of the factors which raise barriers to antimerger relief would be incomplete without mentioning the political-legal environment within which Section 7 is enforced and any deleterious effect this environment might have on the efficacy of the law. Since this is not a study_ in administrative law or political science, the remarks will be brief--though brevity does not indicate a lack ofn severity. At the start of this chapter, the general rule was stated that the longer a merger remains consummated, the more difficult it is to unravel. One of the reasons for the lengthy time Span between the acquisition and the, relief order is that the adjudicative process can be so long. The Methusalah of Merger Cases, the Pillsbury fiasco, was literally litigated to death with the FTC finally dropping the case after-fourteen years and some forty thousand pages of evidence.104 126 That antitrust cases take too long is not a new proposition; the problems of the "big case" have been explored before—-yet still exist. Any lawyer interested in dragging out a merger case has several excellent examples to draw from. The Crown Zellerbach case, for example, lays out an exemplary strategy for lengthening this time span which in turn is so helpful in avoiding structural relief. In the trial records of that case, pages 11 through 16A9 are consumed by pre-trial jockeying for position, corres- pondence for extensions, pre—trial conferences, resetting of trial dates, admissability of evidence questions, etc. These tactics ran out over three years of the judicial clock. One who reads the trial records in these cases cannot help but be overwhelmed by the legal jockeying and delay, nit—picking, the legal moves and countermoves—- illustrated by briefs such as these: Brief In Support Of Interlocutory Appeals From Hearing Examiner's Ruling Denying‘ Motion Of National Dairy Products Corpor— ation To Quash Subpoena Dated December 15, 1958,105 Respondent's Brief On Appeal From The Order Of The Hearing Examiner Denying Its Motion To Strike Proponent's Answer To Respondent's Request For Admissions And To Have The Matters Of Eact In Such Request Be Deemed Admitted.10 Memorandum Reply To "Answering Brief To Respondent's Interlocutory Appeals From Hearing Examiner's Ruling" And "Answer Opposing Request For Oral Argument 0n Respondent's Interlocutory Appeal."107 7" 127 Briefs such as these may be very necessary and integral to the litigative process; the author is not qualified to judge. But there is no doubt that they lengthen the time span--and structural relief becomes less probable. The impact of politics on antimerger relief decrees should not be discounted—-or minimized. That the Johnson administration will not be distinguished for its emphasis on antitrust enforcement is well known. A general directive to "go easy" in antitrust from the President, without a doubt, filters down into relief negotiations. At times political "interference" has directly altered a relief decree. The most impressive display of this is show by Public Law 89—356, the Banking bill passed in 1966.108 This bill was in direct response to antimerger activity directed against banking——and specifically nullified three court divestiture orders! Even those who have resigned themselves to the role of strong lobbies and powerful special interest groups in a democracy cannot help but be somewhat disturbed by the determined and successful efforts of the- banking interests to ram this bill through Congress. Of course, a piece of legislation is not always neces— sary to weaken a relief decree. In the Union Carbide relief, a June 1963,1etter from one of Louisiana's senators extolling the virtues of selling the Visking plants to Ethyl Corporation was sent to the Commission; four months later, the sale was allowed. Senator Pastore ". . . preached anti-poverty to the 128 Justice Department and has all but undone the Government‘s assault on Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corp.'s acquisition from U.S. Rubber of a wire and cable plant in Bristol, 109 R. I." The divestiture order in the above case was dropped.110 Political pressure, played from the poverty and unem— ployment angles, also influenced the Continental Can relief decree111 and the Justice Department's decisions not to challenge the Firestone—Seiberling Rubber Co. and General . . . 2 Electric—Landers, Frary & Clark acqu1s1tions.ll Conclusions What can we conclude on the general problem of asset restoration as a barrier to efficient antimerger enforcement? First, that the time span between the acquisition and the divestiture order can, in a dynamic market setting, prevent or make very difficult the unscrambling of two firms. Second, divestiture of "bits 'n pieces" of an acquisition, the so-ealled partial divestiture, has not distinguished itself for efficacy. Third, a loose handling of the divest— iture-of post-acquisition improvements could afford an economic incentive to firms to expand in violation of- Section 7, planning on divesting the acquired assets several years hence. The answer to these problems, the task of the next chapter, involves cutting down or eliminating this time span. It does not require some per se rule regarding 129 partial vs. full divestiture or regarding the divestiture. of post—acquisition improvements. Rather it requires a closer adherence to the principle that relief iS'a failure, if sufficient assets are not excommunicated to re—establish an independent firm of sufficient size to survive. Normally, this would seem to require full divestiture including any post-acquisition.improvements. With regard to marketing orders in antimerger enforce- ment we can conclude: l. The marketing order is considered by some to be a substitute for structural relief.- This is an error, for the marketing order is making the Clayton Act a criminal statute, heavily fining executives who arrange anticompetitive mergers; nor is it following Mencken's suggestion to make a violation of the antitrust laws punishable by capital punishment! The answer lies in structuringealegal framework better! to prevent specific anticompetitive mergers before their consummation and, if this fails, satisfactorily to unravel these mergers after the fact--and by so doing to deter future anticompetitive mergers. Three specific areas will be considered as a means of stimulating such a preventive environment. 149 Facilitating Structural-Relief The first specific area is the encouragement of- structural relief——along the lines endorsed in the previous two chapters. This "encouragement" must be partly atti— tudinal and educational in nature. Legislation requiring structural relief in antimerger cases would not be wise, for in some cases such relief is impossible. Instead, there is need for the government antitrust enforcers to impress upon the courts the need for structural relief in antimerger cases. And there is evidence that there are government antitrust enforcers who themselves are in need of this education--particularly in the negotiation of consent orders. There is need for a change in attitude on the part of those responsible for the relief decree to~ realize that divestiture is not only a logical requirement in antimerger cases, it is a minimal requirement. The Spin—Off. To facilitate structural relief, perhaps even as a; - measure to encourage antitrusters that such relief is not beyond their grasp in antimerger cases, legislation designed to encourage "spin—off" would be desirable. Spin-off is a simple way of dividing a corporation into two parts without the problem of finding a satisfactory buyer for one of the parts. Spin—off, therefore, under most circumstances, meets the ideal structural criteria of establishing a new inde— pendent firm. 150 Assume Firm X acquires Firm Y in violation of Section 7. Under a spin-off order, Firm X would reorganize Firm Y as a corporation and sell the assets of Y to Corporation Y in return for all of Y's capital stock; then Firm X distributes the Y stock to its own stockholders in proportion to their stockholdings in X. When the spin—off is completed, the stockholders in X will have retained their holdings in X but will also own Corporation Y's stock. If-the managers of X and Y are not allowed to have holdings in Y and X respec- tively, and the shares of the two companies are sufficiently dispersed, then, barring collusion between the two, X and Y will be independent firms again, the anticompetitive merger being neatly undone.22 This process has been an option in several merger cases. In the Crown Zellerbach case the FTC staff, not enthused about St. Helens going to Boise—Cascade, tried to work out a spin-off order.23 But Arthur Dean, speaking as Crown's counsel, said he was appalled by the complexities of establishing a new corporation-—that Crown's preference was for a sale. So it was. In the Commission order against Kaiser Cement & Gypsum Corporation's acquisition of Olympic Portland Cement Company, Kaiser was given the option of either divestiture or spin—off.2Ll Kaiser took the divestiture option——selling Olympic to Pittsburgh Plate Glass, much to the dissatis- faction of two FTC Commissioners.25 151 Spin—off was available to Foremost Dairies as an acceptable method of complying with its relief order. The company's southeastern region was first going to be spun off but then was sold instead to Home Town Foods, Inc.26l After losing its Supreme Court appeal, Consolidated Foods was given the option of selling Gentry to an acceptable buyer or establishing a new Gentry via a spin-off method. Consolidated considered a variation on the spin—off method, namely spinning off a block of stock representing the new Gentry to an underwriter for sale to the general public. But here again the option was not taken, Gentry being sold instead 27 to Basic Food Materials Incorporated. General Dynamics, in ridding itself of Liquid Carbonics, has the spin-off option open to it also.28 But I am not aware of any case where the spin—off option has been successfully used in a Celler- Kefauver case. Companies have several reasons for avoiding Spin—off. For one, it does not allow them to pick a buyer. There is also considerable uncertainty in the Spin-off method because of its novelty, and also due to the uncertainty of how the new Operation will fare on its own. Under a spin-off, the managers of the acquiring firm dare not bleed the spun—off assets of important resources or personnel lest it not survive on its own thereby hurting their own stockholders' interests. The Spin-Off and Taxation But there is another obstacle to spin—off——which could be cured by legislation. This is the tax barrier to this form of relief. There is no provision in the Internal Revenue Code giving any special consideration for involuntary sales pursuant to antitrust orders. Under certain conditions, the stock spun off to the acquiring shareholders constitutes a dividend and is therefore taxable as income. It was this income tax on its shareholders, for example, which discouraged Foremost from using the spin-off method. For that matter when a company complies with a divestiture order, it may have to pay capital gains tax, the same as a voluntary sale; this also discourages companies from agreeing to structural relief.29 The government's hand in securing structural relief would be strengthened substantially if legislation were passed changing the status of structural relief orders to involuntary conversions for tax purposes, so that no gain or loss would be recognized from either a divestiture or spin~ off. Companies would be economically encouraged to accept structural relief. The government would be in a better bargaining position to demand this sort of relief, partic— ularly with courts which still consider structural relief to be punitive. And by so doing, companies which had planned to consummate anticompetitive acquisitions would realize that the chances of keeping the fruits of their acquisition would 153 be substantially lessened. Such legislation is needed to facilitate divestiture. The loss in tax revenue would be offset by the gains in antitrust enforcement.3O Preliminary Injunctions Sincetflkaobstacles to structural relief can be formidable, optimum antimerger enforcement would concentrate on stOpping all anticompetitive mergers before their consum— mation. The preliminary injunction is one technique to nip a merger in the bud, thereby eliminating much if not all of the relief problem. The preliminary injunction is simply a court order telling a party that it is not to do something until some issue concerning its proposed action has been settled.31 In a merger case, then, a preliminary injunction might order two firms planning a merger to hold off until the court was satisfied that no Section 7 violation was likely to occur. If a judge felt strongly that a proposed merger would quite likely violate Section 7, he might grant a preliminary I injunction against the merger until the legality was-settled in the main action. On the other hand, if the government is not sustained in its request, it would still be free to continue its suit even though no preliminary relief was, given. At law, the preliminary injunction does not constitute a determination of legality or illegality. Under Section 15 of the Clayton Act, the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission may petition the 154 court for such orders to prevent or restrain Violations of Section 7, and the court may "make such temporary restraining order or prohibition as shall be demed just in the premises." The issuance is in the discretion of the court after a summary hearing on the merits of the order.3 As might have been predicted, the government has not always been successful in obtaining this form of relief. From 1953 through 1964, the Department of Justice received thirteen preliminary injunctions in Section 7 cases. In 1965 it lost three out of four requests.33 34 Through 1966, the FTC has been successful only once. Granting a Preliminary Injunction A judge, in deciding upon a preliminary injunction request, usually weighs three factors, the most important of which seems to be the probability that the applicant would prevail in the main action. For example, in rejecting preliminary relief in the Nashville Bank case the judge made it quite evident that he did not see anticompetitive aspects in the merger in question.35 A second consideration a judge might weigh is the probability and extent of injury to the applicant, if-the motion were denied but the applicant prevailed in the main action. Preliminary relief has been denied when the judge became convinced that divestiture, though perhaps expensive and even difficult, would still be possible should the applicant prevail in the main action.36 155 And finally, a preliminary injunction hangs in part upon the probable loss and/or inconvenience to the opposing parties. For example, in rejecting preliminary relief in the FMC-American Viscose merger, Judge Harris was strongly influenced by the claim of Avisco stockholders that they would suffer heavy pecuniary losses if the merger were delayed.37 Where the judge has doubts that the opposing party would prevail in the main action, and feels that structural relief may not take place later, he is likely to be far more lenient in granting preliminary injunctions. For example Judge Rosenberg said: I find it difficult to understand the defendant's contention that this case be allowed to go to final hearing without injunction.and that if a violation . . . has occurred that the remedy of divestiture then be effected. Considering the hardships of divestiture actions with their ramifi— cations and complications and their painful impacts upon all whom they touch, it is hard to understand that such a device can be reasonably considered as the ultimate remedy to be employed here.3 The Strategy of Opposing Preliminary Injunctions The approach taken by companies opposing a request for a preliminary injunction is threefold. The first step is to indicate that the government has not adequately shown the probability that the merger will violate Section 7; i.e., the respondents try to place the burden of a full— scale investigation on the government before such an order 156 is issued. For example, in the Brown Shoe case the respondents argued: "The drastic remedy should be granted only upon a clear showing of violation_and the necessity for its employment."39 The second tack is to impress upon the judge that greater injury will be inflicted upon the company if the injunction is granted than would be borne by the government if the injunction were denied. Companies often claim that their merger must be consummated immediately, so that granting even a temporary injunction against the merger will completely and forever frustrate the merger. Denying the petition supposedly injures the government only slightly "since divestiture is always available" should the government win the full trial on the merits. In the proposed Chrysler-Mack merger, the two companies informed the judge specifically that granting a preliminary injunction in this case would be tantamount to a permanent injunction};0 Continental Can argued in a similar vein, adding that the motion should be denied since the court always had the ". . . power to order Continental to divest itself of the assets so acquired . . . (and) . . . Continental is prepared to assume the risk of adverse consequences, what» ever they may be."41 The third approach in avoiding a preliminary injunction is to convince the judge that it is unnecessary since the two companies will be operated separately anyway and that, 157 consequently, divestiture will be no problem in the event the merger is found in violation of the law.J42 There have- been several such arrangements whereby the mergers have been consummated under some sort of separate operating agreement,“3 and there has been support for this type of order since it supposedly offers the advantage of allowing the merger to be consummated without hindering the prospect of structural relief.“l Relying in part upon this no-commingling, separate operation argument, others have been able to convince the courts (or Commission) to allow the merger to be made, pending adjudication, provided that the assets are not- commingled.b'5 The arguments behind these three approaches to avoiding preliminary relief orders are worthy of consideration. In Support of Preliminary Injunctions To argue that the government's request for preliminary relief should be denied, because it has not "shown a clear violation of Section 7," simply does not wash. The fact that the government has filed suit indicates the strong possibility of a violation. Granting a preliminary injunction without a clear showing of guilt is not in contra~ diction to the principle of law that the respondent is innocent until proven guilty. Those who so argue need to be reminded that a preliminary injunction is neither a finding 158 of law, nor is it permanent. It is rather " . . . inter- locutory, tentative, provisional, ad interim, impermanent, mutable, not fixed or final or conclusive, characterized by its for-the—time-beingness."l46 The second argument, that preliminary relief would frustrate an otherwise lawful merger, i.e. one which would survive the main action, is important since, if valid, it seriously weakens any casezfix:increased use of preliminary relief. Is it true that granting preliminary relief causes permanent injury to the opposing parties, nullifying in effect an otherwise lawful merger? There is evidence that a government suit does under- mine merger plans. There are several instances where merely attacking a proposed merger is sometimes sufficient in itself to halt merger negotiations. The following merger negotiations, for example, were discontinued after the government either brought suit or announced its intention of doing s02”7 America Corporation-Republic American Hospital Supply-W. H. Curtin & Co. Calumet National Bank-of Hammond-Mercantile National Bank Chase Manhattan Bank-Diner's Club Inc. Commercial Credit Corp.-General Finance Corp. Humble Oil Co.-Tidewater Oil Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical-Kawneer Co. Molson Breweries Ltd.-Theo Hamm Brewing Co. Pittsburgh Brewing Co.-Duquesne Brewing Co. Stauffer Chemical Co.-American Viscose Corp. Russell Stover Candies-Fanny Farmer Candy ShOps Thrifty Drug Stores, Inc.—Save—On Drugs, Inc. Title Insurance & Trust—Title Guarantee Co. 159 Other firms which have dropped merger plans prior to a finding of illegality but after a preliminary restraining order include Abbot Laboratories, Allied Chemical Corp., Amfac Inc., Chrysler Corp., Herff Jones, Ingersoll Rand Co., Parents Magazine and Pennzoil; all of these have. foregone proposed acquisitions prior to the finding of illegality but following a temporary ban.“8 Do these examples indicatetmat it is the preliminary ban which is the decisive factor in scuttling merger plans—— even though no Section 7 violation has yet been found? It might, but the answer is not so affirmative once the post hoc ergo propter hoc smoke has cleared. In the first place, some of the above plans were scuttled, not because a prelim— inary ban (or much-less the government attack) in and of itself forced this action, but rather because in the course of the preliminary litigation the respondent becomes aware that the merger would not stand in the main action. To blame the preliminary injunction as the causative factor offers a convenient ”out” from an unlawful acquisition. The argument that the negotiations cannot survive the "delay" of a preliminary injunction also seems a bit far— fetched. Merger consultants constantly admonish managers to proceed with caution, not haste. One successful acquirer has been quoted as saying: "We have never been in a hurry to acquire anybody. Several of our acquisitions took over one year and the largest took two years.”49 In surveying 160 the correspondence in relief fileS—-correspondence between firms.selling assets and proSpective purchasers-—one does not find this "must buy immediately" attitude which seems to prevail when an acquisition is threatened with a preliminary injunction. And given the present state of merger case law, since Philadelphia Bank, Pabst and Von's, a respondent truly desirous of merging, hampered only by a preliminary injunction, can have the issue at law settled far quicker than in the earlier days of Section 7 enforcement.50- The main burden placed on firms by a preliminary. injunction involves renegotiation of terms, repetition of certain legal, clerical and administrative details, and possibly refiling some prospectuses with the SEC. It is quite true that during the time span for litigation, unforeseen circumstances may arise which will frustrate the merger, at least on its original terms. If this should happen, then at least one party to the merger should be grateful for the preliminary injunction! In spite of the no—mingling agreement success in the Spalding case, and even though the final results are not yet in on several other orders of this type, the no— commingling agreement——the third barrier to preliminary injunctions--is a poor substitute for an outright ex ante ban. There are three reasons for this: 1. 161 Preventing commingling is easier said than done. On a purely procedural basis_it has presented~ difficulties. In Brown Shoe the court had to specify and deal with eight different problems to keep Brown and Kinney from mingling. Inevi- tably, issues will come up which engage the: court in a regulatory role attempting to-keep two firms separate though together, apart though joined.51' Allowing the merger to be consummated--but preventing commingling-éstill presents the "buyer problem" if the merger is later found to violate Section 7. While it may be easier to separate. the partners of an unlawful marriage if they: never lived:to‘gether, it still leaves- the problem of with whom one Will live after the annulment. And finally it seems naive to think that an agreement not to mingle can really be effective. For example, Standard Oil of New Jersey proposed a ten point program to own PotaSh Company of America yet keep Potash free from Standard's influence. Judge Shaw wisely rejected the idea that 162 . . . Potash Company of America, Inc. would, in the interim . . . be, and continue to be after divestiture by Jersey, the same oper— ating corporate entity as PCA has been in the past . . . There are many areas in which suggestions from Jersey rather than. directives could affect future policy pending the outcome of this litigation. 2 Or as one judge colorfully put it: "It has been said that after the saber thrust, the wound is still there. The purpose of the injunction is to prevent the wound ."53 Facilitating Prelimingry Relief Consequently, there is a need for legislation enabling the antitrust enforcement agencies to obtain preliminary injunctions more easily. One such piece of legislation was Celler's bill, first presented in the 87th Congress——but never passed.5u This bill would not have given the courts any more authority to issue preliminary injunctions; they have ample authority as is. Instead the bill would have encouraged the courts to give preliminary injunctions less sparingly. Helpful as this bill might be, an even sounder aid to facilitate nipping anticompetitive mergers in the bud would be a bill somewhat analogous to Section 7 (A) of the 1966 Bank Merger Act which provides an automatic stay upon a challenged merger, unless the district court approves it.55 In other words, a law is needed which will reverse the order of proof in preliminary injunction cases——allowing the g- 163 government to seek preliminary relief and placing the burden on the merging parties to show Why the automatic stay should not be continued. Companies should be able to have the stay lifted. But this should be possible only upon a reasonable showing that the acquired firm will be restored as an independent should the merger eventually be found in violation of Section 7. Such a law would dovetail nicely with the pro- ’vision advocated earlier to facilitate Spin—off. Thus, one method which two companies might use to have an auto— matic stay rescinded would be to submit a satisfactory Spin-off plan to the court. But in the absence of such a Plan, the preliminary ban would remain in effect until the termination of the main action. In brief, more effective antimerger enforcement requires either (1) a change in attitude on the part of the Judiciary in providing preliminary relief, or (2) legis- lation reversing the order of proof in preliminary relief cases, placing the burden on the respondent to demonstrate that the merger clearly will not violate Section 7 or that structural relief is likely should the government win the main action. At the minimum, the government should only have to raise doubts about the legality of an acquisition to secure preliminary relief. The notion that the "time" consideration is so all important is spurious. Any pecuniary interests in immediate 164 consummation are subordinate to the public interest. Indeed, the preliminary injunction is in keeping with the general purpose of the Clayton Act-—stopping anticompetitive mergers 56 in their incipiency. Its use should be encouraged. Premerger Notificapion There is nothing presently preventing two companies with marriage plans from asking the approval of the govern- ment. In fact, the government encourages this very thing. But, in the vast majority of cases, the couple prefers to e10pe and let any interested parties learn of the union in the papers or from "friends." Sometimes this takes time, and an annulment becomes less likely. The fact that the government has an advisory program on proposed mergers was mentioned in Chapter II. Recall that this was seldom used, since most businessmen are "reluctant to dig their own grave." Because there is presently no requirement that companies planning to merge must report their intentions to either the Federal Trade Commission or to the Antitrust Division, these two agencies must go elsewhere to learn of mergers which might violate Section 7. Where must they go? They review newspapers, the financial press, investment brochures, and trade journals for information on prospective and consummated mergers. Sometimes, the investigation of one merger provides infor- mation on others. Occasionally, stockholders of one of the 165 parties to a proposed union, peSSimistic about its effects on their holdings, will even write the government hoping that a federal antimerger suit will emasculate the merger talks! Stanley Barnes, the former and most able chief of the Antitrust Division, once testified that ". . . a good.part of the time of the junior members of the staff is occupied‘ with ferreting out, before they occur, those mergers with potential anticompetitive effects."57 In addition, he stated that one third of the mergers which have involved. detailed study by his agency were either already consummated, beforehand or else were consummated before any preliminary investigation could be completed. Mergers less likely to. come to the government's attention are those by closely held firms, partial stock acQuisitions where the percentage pur— chased, though perhaps small, is still large enough to yield working control, and small mergers, often in intrastate commerce, noted only in the local press. Premerger Notification Legislation Several bills have been-introduced to enact some sort of premerger notification program.~ For five consecutive years, President Eisenhower recommended such a bill in his- Economic Report of theAPresident‘.58 In the eighty-fourth Congress,Senator Sparkman introduced S. 2075 proposing that no firm could participate in a merger, if it had a net worth of over $1 million, until ninety days after notifying both 166 the FTC and the Antitrust Division of its intentions. In the House, Representative Patman preposed H. R. 6748 requiring advance notice of any merger involving a company with a capital surplus and undivided profits of more than $1 million. This bill called for a thirty—day post-notifi— cation waiting period during which the companies were to supply the government with any information requested con— cerning the merger.59 Variations of this sort of legis— lation have beenzipart of subsequent Congresses but-without success. Both the Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission have supported premerger notification legislation; 'but-their requests have not been granted--which of course is not a novel state of affairs. The government supports premerger legislation because it feels antimerger enforcement will be improved thereby; that mergers which now go undetected, or are detected later than might be liked, would no longer remain-so; that personnel now scanning public sources for potential Section 7 candidates could be used elsewhere more productively. The business community, on the other hand, has been quite strongly united against the various premerger notifi— cation bills. A sampling of firms listed on the New York and American Stock Exchanges indicated ninety per cent 60 Why has the legislation not Opposed such legislation. drawn huzzahs from the business community? For a variety of reasons which merit attention. 167 Draftinga Notification Statute .One sticky problem, never satisfactorily solved, is the drafting of such a bill to meet the objectives sought be the legislation. An-idpgl bill would be worded so as to elicit a notice from every merger which was likely to violate Section 7——and no others. Ideally, all other firms would be free of the trouble and expense of filing; and the government would be free of the trouble and expense of reviewing those proposed mergers not going-to violate Section 7. Obviously, such an ideal bill could never be drafted, And there is legitimate concern whether any bill could be drafted which, in even~a-far from ideal way, would accom- plish what is expected of the legislation. For example, a premerger notification bill needs exceptions; the govern- ment would be flooded with notices if every little business which was taken over by another business had to file; in addition these small businesses should not be troubled with ~the expense of filing. Thus, the bills have to establish some sort of floor to the reporting requirement. But an even more troubling aspect of the drafting problem is exempting those industries which have trans- actions, which theoretically might be termed "mergers," but for antimerger purposes are not. For example, in the petroleum industry, independent oil producers often liquidate -their.assets on very short notice to secure capital for 168 financing a new exploratory venture. These transactions are, strictly speaking, mergers, but they are not the type. of merger in which Section 7 enforcers are interested. In~ addition, these transactions must be carried out quickly. The-ninety-, sixty-, or even thirty-day waiting period of premerger bills would often.be too long; the opportunity would be gone.61 Similarly, in the insurance industry, the proposed legislation has raised the objection that it includes transactions which are common and integral parts of the insurance industry—ewhich do not warrant govern- mental notice nor could they be delayed.62' This drafting problem may seem minor but it is not--particularly to those fearful of burdening the business community with more, "unnecessary" reporting. The following groups were suf— ficiently concerned about the law's potential impact on various "normal" transactions.and negotiations in their industries to request special exemption or exceptions of some sort: American Mining Congress . American Pulp & Paper Association 'Life Insurance Association of America Independent Petroleum Association of America Milk Industry Foundation Air Transport Association of America National Coal Association . . Texas Independent Producers & Royalty Owners Association 'Association of American Rairoads "American Merchant Marine Institute American Trucking Associations . Investment Bankers Association of America National Retail Merchants Association and others. 169 Alvord of the American Mining Congress offered a salutary list of amendments needed in a general premerger notifi- cation bill, too long to include here, but providing good background on this problem.63 Other Objections to Notification Even assuming the drafting problem could be solved, i.e., that a bill could be so worded to exclude any reporting of normal business transactions and insignificant mergers, there are still other objections to the bill. A common complaint is that the government agencies might View the bill as a Congressional directive that any merger of sufficient size to meet the reporting requirement is, payma fagig, in violation of Section 7. In short, one objection is that the bill might lead to an improper antimerger enforcement! The importance of secrecy in merger negotiations seems well established.614 A premerger notification bill, if the notices "leaked," could discourage or completely stop some merger negotiations. Some have argued that this constitutes a valid argument against such a bill. Former Antitrust Division chief Bicks replied to this objection that govern— ment antitrust employees would be bound by law not to 65 divulge such information. Another common complaint against premerger notification is the cost. One estimate placed the cost involved in such a notice at "a minimum of $5,000."66 While this estimate seems rather high--my own 170 estimates place it closer to $150--there is no doubt that such legislation would impose some financial cost on the business community.67 Other objections expressed include a "concern" that the government not become swamped with additional paperwork, that the present situation-affords the government adequate opportunity to learn of any important merger, that if it does not, divestiture is always available, and finally the interesting twist offered by the NAM that asking a corpor— ation to report a proposed acquisition is somewhat akin to (and equally as undesirable as) asking an individual to testify againsthimself!68‘ In spite of these objections, premerger notification has evoked a generally favorable response from that portion of-the academic_community interested in the monopoly | problem.69 The reasoning of this group is that the govern- |mentneeds to know about those mergers which will Violate aSection 7 before they are consummated to the find that the “enforcement of Section 7 be improved. But note that premerger notification, as a means to this admirable end, rests on-two premises: 1. that the government does not now know about those mergers likely to violate Section 7 before their consummation 171 2. that if the government did know of them and-had a certain time period in which to examine them prior to consummation, then enforcement would be enhanced. The author doubts the validity of both of these premises, and consequently cannot share in the enthusiasm of some for premerger notification. Regarding the first premise: anyone who has spent time with the Federal Trade Commission cannot help but be impressed with the data gathered on mergers by the Bureau of Economics. A most thorough job is done-—so thorough that the important merger which slips by unnoticed is rare, and more than likely will be a stock acquisition which is~ more easily undone later. True, the FTC staff scans much material to garner these data—-but they are for the most, part material which would be scanned anyway, even if there were some premerger "warning system." In the case of the Antitrust Division, it seems the passage of the 1962 Anti- trust Civil Process Act lessened the need for premerger notification as an informationaldevice.7O The second major premise of those supporting premerger, notification, viz. that it would enhance antimerger enforce— ment via the "waiting period," is also shaky. As the law now stands, the government can bring suit against a merger under Section 7 any time after its consummation-~if the. anticompetitive effects were not apparent at the merger 172 date but became obvious later, the_government could challenge the marger at the later date.7l' Premerger notification would not change the status of this; the government would still be able to legally open a case sometime after the merger's consummation. But if the government is notified of a merger, has sixty or ninety days to make its investigation, and does app bring suit during that time—-that merger will be difficult to unravel at a later date. First, the antitrusters will be reluctant to bring.suit at this-time. And it is not inconceivable that the courts will take a rather dim view of merger suits broughtlnrthe government after it had previously-remained silent during the waiting period and allowed the merger to be made. .Though premerger notification has found strong support 6 in both the legal and economic communities, its accolades ; are not warranted. No evidence clearly demonstrates that :significant mergers are being consummated without the Egovernment's knowledge. This indicates that such a law is inot needed. In addition, the long-run impact of this legis- lation on antimerger enforcement could well be deleterious. y i 1 FOOTNOTES CHAPTER V lEconomic costs are the only ones considered here. The Clayton Act is not a criminal statute; failure to comply will not mean fines or jail sentences for exeCutives. In, addition.there does not seem to be any social or occupa- tional stigma involved in violating Section 7;-if anything, being involved in a merger suit will probably raise an executive's status in the business community. 2WSJ, May 22, 1959, p. l. 3WSJ, July 8, 1965, p. 1. “Compliance File, Continental Baking Co., FTC Docket 7880. SWSJ, July 8, 1965, op. cit. 6U. S. v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corp., BB #1275, Antitrust Division Pleading File, Vol. I. 7See respectively: (Alcoa- Cupples) "Affidavit" of! Charles C. Moran, March 23, 1965, in U. S. v. Aluminum 00. of America, BB #1607, Antitrust Division Pleading File, Vol. III; (Alcoa—Rome) "Defendant' s Proposed Findings Of Fact And Conclusions Of Law On Relief, " November 10,1965, p. 9 in U_§'. v. Aluminum Co. of_America, BB #1512, Anti- trust Division Pleading File, Vol.‘III; (American Radiator) see fn. 8, this chapter; (Continental Baking) "Motion For Extension Of Time, " February 7, 19§33 pp. 7- 8 in Continental Baking, op. cit.; (Continental Can Affidavit of Helmer R Johnson, July, 1964, pp. 3— 4 in U. S v. Continental Can Co., BB #1301, Antitrust Division “Pleading File, Vol. III; (Foremost) see fn. 10, this chapter; (National Homes) see fn. 9, this chapter; (Reynolds Metals) "Petition.of. Respondent To Reopen Cause For New And Additional Evidence Or Alternatively For A Rehearing And For Modification Of Order Of January 21,1960," March 11,1960 in Reynolds , Metals Co., FTC Docket 7009; (Ryder) "Respondent's Petition To Modify Final Judgment, " January 15, 1962, in e U. s v. Elder System, Inc., BB #1564, Antitrust Division Pleading File, Vol. I. 173 F._.h- a 174 8"American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corporation 9 Month Report to Stockholders,” as quoted in George D. McCarthy, Acqpisitions and Mergers (New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1963), p. 40. 9 National Homes Corporation, 1962 Annual Report, p. 10"In Brief," Mergers & Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Winter, 1966), pp. 7—8. 11Brown Shoe Co., 1963 Annual Report, p. 22. 12Crown Zellerbach, 1964 Annual Report, p. 3. 13International Paper Co., 1960 Annual Report, p. 28. l“Owens—Illinois "Press Release," April 21, 1965. 15Union Carbide Corp., 1964 Annual Report, p. 2. 16A. G. Spalding & Bros., 1962 Annual Report, p. 3. 17ypg, June 21, 1960, p. 6 and ypg, June 28, 1960, p, l8Crown Zellerbach, op. cit. 19Owens-Illinois,"Report of first quarter operations, 1966." 2OWalton Hamilton and Irene Till, "Antitrust in Action," U.S. TNEC Monograph No. 16 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1941), p. 81. 21James Harwood, "The Mystique of Antitrust," Mgrgers & Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Fall, 1965), p. 34» 22For more information on the spin-off, see Stanley Siegel, "When Corporations Divide: A Statutory and Financial Analysis," Harvard Law Review, 79 (January, 1966), pp. 534— 570. 23"Memorandum to the Commission from the Bureau of Restraint of Trade," March 19, 1964, in Crown Zellerbach, FTC Docket 6180. 2MBNA ATRR 194: A—8. 25BNA ATRR 263: A-4. 26"Compliance Reports," Foremost Dairies, FTC Docket 6495. 175 27"Compliance Reports," Consolidated Foods Corp., FTC Docket 7000. 28 BNA ATRR 283: A—23. 29Tax aspects of antitrust cases are explored in more detail in: "Analysis, Income Tax Consequences of Antitrust Payments," BNA ATRR 268: B—11 and Roger Noall and Troxell D. Chase, "Tax Aspects of Antitrust Proceedings," Tax Law Review, 18 (January, 1963), pp. 213—250. 30There is some precedent for such legislation. Distributions of stock pursuant to the 1935 Public Utility Holding Company Act (I. R. C. Secs. 1081-1083) ordered by the SEC and those ordered by the FRB pursuant to the 1956 Bank Holding Company Act (I. R. C. Secs. 1101-1103) were covered by such provisions. Public Law 87—403 of 1962 provided that the distribution of stock in the duPont—GM case would.be taxed as a return on capital rather than as dividend income. In fact the tax laws should encourage all spin-offs, not just those pursuant to Section 7 orders. If all spin—offs were exempt from income or capital gains taxation, there might be a voluntary decon— centration. 31No distinction will be made here between the preliminary injunction and the temporary restraining order. 32For the procedural framework of preliminary relief, see "Note, Preliminary Injunctions and the Enforcement of Section 7 of the Clayton Act," New York Univ. Law Review, 40 (October, 1965). pp. 772—774.“ 33 Ibid., fn. 9. 3“It was widely believed at one time that the FTC did not have such right of petition. As a result many antitrust observers argued that the Commission also should have the authority to seek preliminary relief in the federal courts. 7 The FTC had tried twice to secure such relief and each time different circuit courts ruled against the Commission. See ' ETC v. International Paper Co., 241 F. 2d 372 (1956) and Egg v. Dean Foods Co., 356 F. 2d 481 (1966). Bills were ‘ introduced in Congress to give the FTC this authority but none was successful. How surprising it was to find later, in spite of these defeats by the courts and Congress, in spite of the bulk of legal opinion to the contrary, that the FTC really had this authority all along-—thanks to five ardent admirers of strong Section 7 enforcement on the Supreme Court! See FTC v. Dean Foods Co., 384 U.S. 597 (1966). 176 35In spite of reports by the Federal Reserve Board, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and the Department of Justice on the adverse effects of this merger! See ULS. v. Third National Bank of Nashville, 1964 CCH Trade Cases Par. 71,209 at 79,830; see also ULS. v. Crocker—Anglo National Bank, 1963 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,934 at 78,719 and U.S. v. Gimbel Brothers, Inc., 202 F. Supp. 779 at 780 TI962). ' 36See for example: U.S. v. Food Machinery Corp. & American Viscose Cor ., 1963—CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70:826 at 78,364; U.S. v. Third National Bank of Nashville, ibid., at 79,830; 9:9: v. Crocker—Anglo National Bank, ibid., at 78,729. 37 Ibid., at 78,365 and 78,367. 38U.S v. Ingersoll Rand Co., 218 F. Supp. 530 at 542 (19637? aff'd. 320 F. 2d 509 (1963); quoted with approval in U.S. v. Chrysler Corp. & Mack Trucks, 232 F. Supp. 651 at 658_(l964); see also Crane Co. V. Briggs Mfg. Co., 80 F. 2d 747 at 750 (19605. 39"Memorandum Of Law On Behalf Of Defendants In Opposition To Plaintiff's Motion For A Preliminary Injunction," 'p. 17 in U.S. v. Brown Shoe Co., Inc., BB #1266, Antitrust Division PIEading File, Vol. I, underlining mine. MOU.S. v. Chrysler Corp. & Mack Trucks, op. cit. at 659; see also U.S. v. Von's Grocery Co., 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,698. 71"Memorandum In Opposition To Temporary Restraining Order," p. 7 in U.S. v. Continental Can Co., BB #1301, Antitrust Division Pleading File, Vol. I. 72For example see "Defendant's Memorandum In Oppo- sition~To Plaintiff's Motion For Preliminary Injunction," April, 1960, p. 3 in pig. v. Aluminum Company of America, (Alcoa—Rome), BB #1512, Antitrust Division Pleading File, Vol. I. 73See for example: ULS. v. Aluminum Compan Of America, (Alcoa—Rome), 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 59,727; EL§3 v. Aluminum Company of America, (Alcoa—Cupples), 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,419; U.S. v. Brown Shoe Co., Inc., 1956 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,—244; ULS. V. Greater Buffalo Press, Inc., 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,380. 177 “u"Note, Preliminary Relief for the Government under Section 7 of the Clayton Act," Harvard Law Review, 79 (December, 1965), p. 393. 75Allis—Chalmers—Simplicity, BNA ATRR 222: A—15; AluminflnnLtd.—National Distillers & Chemical, BNA ATRR 182: A—l6; Falstaff Brewing—Narragansett Brewing, BNA ATRR 218: A—8; First National City Bank—Hilton Credit Corp., BNA ATRR 234: A—lO; Rheingold Brewery—Jacob Ruppert, BNA ATRR 227: A—9; Phillips Petroleum—Tidewater, Anti— trust & Trade Regulation Newsletter, 5 (August 25, 1966). M6Hamilton Watch Co. v. Benrus Watch Co., 206 F. 2d' 738 at 7 2 1953 . 77See America Corp., BNA ATRR 69: A—l3, 175: A—4; American Hospital, 202: A-3, 228: A—7; Calumet National, 120: A-4; Chase Manhattan, 249: A—ll; Commercial Credit, 168: A—15, 169: A—8; Humble 011, 145: A—7; Kaiser, 73: A-ll; Molson Breweries, 193: A-6; Pittsburgh Brewing, 234: A-2; 236: A—l8; Stauffer Chemical, 65: A—8, 72: A—l4; Russell Stover, 198: A—13, 207: A-l6; Thrifty Drug, 57: A-20, 207: A—16; Title Insurance, 220: A—5. This is not to imply that companies do not merge if the government files suit or indicates to them that a suit is being prepared. Witness the reaction of such corpor— ations as Mead, Cenco Instrument, First National Bank of Hawaii, and Ritter Co. See respectively: WSJ, June 1, 1966, p° 8; WSJ, October 1, 1965, p. 22; wst‘Juiy 27, 1966, p. 3; BNA ATRR 199: A—6. 1 "" 78See Abbot, BNA ATRR 179: A—5, 181: A—9, 217: A_9; Allied Chemical, 145: A-ll, 153: A—5; Amfac, 276: A-6; Chrysler, 160: A—9, 162: A-16; Herff Jones, 222: A—3, 288: A-4; Ingersoll Rand, 93: A—l3, 143: A—18; Parents Magazine, 55: A—9, 58: A-6; Pennzoil, 236: A—9, 237: A—ll, 79The "chief executive officer of a successful acquirer" as quoted by Forrest D. Wallace, "Some Principles of Acquisition,” The Corporate Merger, ed. William Alberts and goel Sega11(Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1966), p. l 7. 50 U.S Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321 0 V0 (1963); U.S. v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546 (1966); ' U.S. v. Von s Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270 (1966). 178 51See U. S. v. Brown Shoe CO.L Inc., Op. cit. Par. 68, 244 at —71, 117; see also the problems in U. S. v. Greater Buffalo Press,pInc., BNA ATRR 53: A— 10 and 85: A—22. 52U.S. v. Standard Oil of New Jersey, 1965 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 71, 503 at 81,235; see also U. S. v. Ingersoll Rand, op. cit. at 543. 53 54"Analysis, Preliminary Injunctions and Temporary Restraining Orders in Merger Cases," BNA ATRR 52: B—l. 55 Crane Co. v. Briggs Mfg. Co., op. cit. at-750. 12 U.S.C. 1828 07a. 56See U. s v.-Brown Shoe Co., 370 U.S. 294 at 346 (1962). ‘ 7Testimony of Stanley Barnes in U. S. ,Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Hearings, Legislation Affecting Corporate Mergers, 84th Cong., 2nd. Sess., May—June, 1956, p. 162. 8 5 See Economic Report(s) of the President (Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office), January, 1956, pp. 78— 79; 1957, p. 5151958, p. 64; 1959, p 53; 1960, p 0 59Joseph Burns, A Study of the Antitrust Laws (New York: Central Book Co., 1958): p. 311. 60A Report on Results of a Survey of Business Opinion Regarding Premerger Notification Legislation (New York: Diversification Institute, affiliate of Boni, Watkins, Jason & Co.) 61Testimony Oerussell B. Brown in 1956 Hearings, Op. cit., p. 237. 62 Testimony of Thomas A. Bradshaw in ibid., p. 296. 63Test1mony of Ellsworth Alvord in ibid., p. 275; see also Joseph Burns, op. cit., pp. 316—319. 6“See the excellent book by Myles L. Mace and George G. Montgomery, Management Problems of Corporate Acquisitions (Boston: Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1962), , 132 179 65Robert A. Bicks, "Recent Legal Developments: The Department of Justice," in Legal, Financial, and Tax Aspects of Mergers and Acquisitions, Financial Management Series #114 (New York: American Management Association, 1957), p. 75. 66Testimony of Benjamin Castle in 1956 Hearings, op. cit., p. 244. 671 am indebted to Mr. Norman Hahn, CPA, Vice— president of the Kalamazoo Paper Co. for this estimate. 68Testimony of Harvey Crow in 1956 Hearings, gp. cit., p. 222. See for example: Carl Kaysen and Donald F. Turner, Antitrust Polic (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 19595, p. 258; Joel B. Dirlam, "The Celler—Kefauver Act: A Review of Enforcement Policy," in U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Administered Prices: A Compendium on Public Policy, 88th Cong., lst Sess., 1963, p. 130; Charles F. Phillips and George R. Hall, "Economic and Legal Aspects of Merger Litigation,"' Univ. of Houston Business Review, 10 (Fall, 1963), pp. 58—59; J. F. Weston, The Role of Mergers in the Growth of Lar e Firms (Berkeley: University ovaaliforn a Press, 19535, p. 99. 70See in general, R. K.-Decker, "The Civil Investi— gative Demand," Kentucky Law Journal, 51 (Spring, 1963), pp. 449—465; see also testimony of Lee Loevinger in U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Hearings, Authorization for Department of Justice to Make Demand for Evidence in Civil Antitrust Investigations, June, 1961, p. 49; Annual Report of the Attorney General of the United States (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 19645, p. 98. 7164 Stat. 1125 at 1126. CHAPTER VI CONCLUSION The "Real" Impact of Section 7 The argument can be made that the "real" impact of an antimerger law lies with factors other than the actual undoing of those few mergers the government attacks; that the law accomplishes its purpose p93 by the unraveling of unlawful mergers but rather by its impact upon ". mergers Egg consummated and which, therefore, never appear, on a Commission or courtdocket."l This line of reasoning, certainly not without.credence, rests on the following notion: since 1890 the ghost of Senator Sherman has supposedly been a member of every corpor— ation's board of directors, influencing them against monop- ; olizing; now, since 1950, the spirit of Messrs. Geller and a Kefauver also sits on these boards, participating in corporate s merger.decisions, and often casting the deciding nay vote. ‘ In other words, the real thrust of Section 7 does not come , through its dissolving of actual mergers; its impact lies in the deterrence of-anticompetitive mergers that-would other- wise have been attempted. The difficulties of determining the extent that corpor_ ations have been dissuaded from mergers because of Section 7 are obvious. No one knows the extent to which the antimerger law has been the critical factor in tabling merger plans, 180 181 though such knowledge would indeed be a valuable contri— bution to merger literature. The "Real" Impact and the Fortune 500 While it is beyond the scope of this study to delve into this question, there is some evidence available which indicates that the antimerger law does have a more than de minimus impact at the merger planning stage. National Economic Research Associates questioned Fortune's 500 largest manufacturing firms in an effort to learn if the "anti-trust climate" has limited merger activity. Of those responding, twenty-eight per cent said they had abandoned mergers due to antitrust factors.2 Unfortunately the interview method leaves much to be desired. In thisv case, it tells nothing about mergers consummated in spite of antitrust factors, nor does it indicate the extent to which the law alone was the deciding factor in stopping merger plans. Neither is it obvious what constitutes a "plan" to merge. One firm's "plan" to merge could be far more (or less) definite than another's "plan." The ”Real" Impact and the Dairy Industry Mueller's work on mergers in the dairy industry sheds a more telling light on this conjectural impact of the law.3 The dairy industry has undergone rather remarkable concen— tration as the result of mergers; indeed the eight largest dairy companies acquired approximately 1800 concerns in the 182 period 1920 to 1950.LI In the six years from 1950 through 1955, these eight firms continued active acquisition programs, acquiring 426 dairy concerns.5 But in the next year, 1956, the FTC issued Section 7 complaints against the nation's four largest dairy concerns.6 These complaints alone seemed to have an impact upon merger activity by the large firms in the industry. In the following six—year period, 1956 through 1961, these same eight firms made only 165 acquisitions. Even more signifi— cant, from 1962 through 1964, the big eight consummated only I; acquisitions.7 Interestingly, 1962 was the year in which the Commission handed down its first decision against one of the four largest firms.8 Consequently, there is an excellent case that in the dairy industry the antimerger law has had an impact in stopping acquisitions beyond the number of consummated acquisitions actually dissolved by Section 7. This is further substantiated by the fact that mergers by firms pp: in the top eight have continued at about the same acquisition rate as existed prior to the Commission’s complaints.9 The antimerger law seems to be the causative variable for the decline in merger activity by the industry's leaders. The "Real" Impact and the Cement Industry The cement industry is one which has undergone con— siderable merging in the last fifteen years, with horizontal consolidation at the cement production level, and vertical 183 merging between cement producers and cement users. Though the number of these mergers has not anywhere approached those recorded in the dairy industry, this horizontal and vertical integration in cement and into ready—mixed concrete has provoked at least twelve FTC complaints since 1960. If Section 7 really has this "hidden power" to stop mergers at the planning stage, to the extent the FTC is successful in winning these cases, one would expect to find an impact on merger rates in this industry. In the cement industry, the FTC recorded the following acquisitions (by capacity) for a sixteen year period.10 1950—1951—— 4.06 million bbls. 1952—1953—— 1.20 million bbls. 1954-1955-— 6.65 million bbls. l956—l957-—24.95 million bbls. l958-l959——25.20 million bbls. 1960—196l-—23.85 million bbls. 1962—1963—— 3.85 million bbls. 1964-1965—— 9.30 million bbls. Note that the six—year period from 1956 through 1961 was a time when considerable cement capacity changed hands, thirty—three plants in all. Note too, that after 1961 the acquisition rate dropped off considerably. In 1960 and 1963 the FTC filed complaints against two of the above mergers, Permanente—Olympic Portland and Diamond Alkali-Bessemer, winning both cases at the Commission 1 In each case, divestiture in 1964 and 1965 respectively.1 was ordered. Since the second FTC complaint, there has not been one horizontal merger in cement until 1965, when there was one, and none involving any cement firm in the industry's 184 top twenty. In fact, with the one exception, all merger activity in cement since the 1961 Diamond Alkali—Bessemer union, has been either of the market or product extension variety. Interestingly enough, the FTC has not attacked any cement mergers of this type.12 The 1960's saw an increase in vertical integration from cement to ready-mixed concrete and concrete products via the acquisition route. In the decade 1950 through 1959, there had been an average of only 0.8 such vertical acquisitions per year. But from 1960 through 1965, there was an average of 6.3 per year.13 According to the Cement Report, the FTC has directed the bulk of its antimerger attack against this vertical integration. In a six—year period, it filed ten complaints connected either totally or partially with forward vertical acquisitions by cement companies of ready—mixed concrete or concrete products firms.lu Since the FTC complaints against some of these vertical acquisitions are fairly recent, it is too early to observe, and even attempt to single out, the impact of this antimerger attack on the rate of vertical acquisitions in the industry. But to the extent that the FTC wins these cases gpd secures meaningful struc— tural relief, the number of such vertical acquisitions should decrease if the antimerger law does in fact have this qualitative effect. 185 Additional information is needed on merger rates in various industries to more fully understand the impact Section 7 has upon these rates; consequently the tentative nature of these findings cannot be stressed too much. A decrease in merger rates following some suCCeSSful anti— merger activity does not mean that Section 7 was the chief thwarter. For example, to attribute to Section 7 the honor of stopping all significant horizontal mergers in cement by the filing and winning of two antimerger cases is a post hocergo propter hoc step to be taken with caution. For in the time period covered by the Cement Report, there were only two significant horizontal mergers in cement, the two the FTC attacked. However, since there were not any thereafter, and since the market and product extension types of acquisition which have ppp been attacked continue to take place (though at a decreased rate), there is some basis for believing that Section 7 has-dissuaded some companies from cementing relations with one another. The "Real" Impact ppon Past Violators Another possible teat of the "real" impact of the, antimerger law is its impact upon-those who have been. "caught" in the past. If Section 7 does have the deterrent power, firms which have violated Section 7 or deemed it wise to negotiate a consent decree in the past should be wary of chancing another such unlawful covenant. If Section 7 were a law with exceptionally stiff penalties, one might 186 predict that Section 7 violators would be reluctant, at least cautious, to consummate gpy more mergers. At a minimum, it would be reasonable to predict that past violators would not repeat the offense. Companies who have been the recipients of more than one antimerger complaint are few in number (but large in size)-—such as General Motors, Proctor & Gamble, Alcoa, Continental Can, and Anheuser-Busch. One could attribute the small number of "repeaters" to the small number of complaints that are issued each year relative to the number of acquisitions made. The fact that there are few "repeaters” is not to be interpreted that firms who have been caught have refrained from further merger activity. On the contrary, many of. the firms in this study’s sample have continued to direct rather substantial acquisition campaigns. Of the 39 firms in the sample, at the most only 4 engaged in no further mergers or joint ventures after their original Section 7 encounter.15 Two companies in the sample, Minute Maid and Brillo, were themselves acquired. Examining the merger activity of the firms in this study's sample after they either lost their antimerger case or settled it by consent order does point to one interesting and significant impact of amended Section 7. Just as the impact of Section 7 seems to manifest itself on the 3333 of merger activity in particular industries, Section 7 has had 187 an impact on the direction of the merger activity of the sample firms. An impact upon the direction of a firm's merger endeavors means a change in the structural type of merger it consummates. The "Real" Impact and Diversification For some of the firms, merger activity was directed to foreign countries, with at least nine of the companies entering into one or more acquisitions or joint venture covenants with overseas companies. This is an obvious way to prevent further encounters with the federal antimerger law. Others maintained their merger activity within the United States' boundaries but emphasized acquisitions of a more diversified bent, staying away from the horizontal- vertical acquisitions and consummating instead product— extension and conglomerate acquisitions. These are more immune from the tentacles of the law. For example, Leslie Salt, one of the sample companies, in refraining from further acquisitions of rival salt companies, chose instead to enter a joint venture with a publishing firm to raise trOpical fish! While none of the other sample firms have measured up to Leslie's degree of diversity, one cannot help but be impressed by the diversification moves that have been taken following an encounter with Section 7. Via the acquisition route, American Cyanamid has gone into floor cleaners and 188 shampoos; American Radiator has gone into space technology instrumentation; Anheuser—Busch into can making; General Shoe (Genesco) into clothing stores and clothing manufacture; Hertz into equipment rental; Maremont into aerospace and textile equipment; Schenley into advertising; Sohio into plastic products; Hooker Chemical into feed supplements and medical chemicals; MMM into cameras and pharmaceuticals; National Sugar into flavored syrups; Reynolds Metals into asphalt building products; Scott Paper into plastic coating specialties; Scovill into refrigeration; and Union Carbide into mattresses. This is only a partial list indicating, in a sketchy way, the diversification that often follows a Section 7 encounter. While it is safe to assume that more horizontal and vertical acquisitions would have been made by these firms in the absence of Section 7, one cannot as yet predict that this diversification strategy would pp: also have been adOpted in the absence of Section 7 prosecution. Schenley TEX have bought its advertising agency even if there were no ban on certain other structural types of mergers. On the other hand, Section 7 has contributed to diversification if, in its absence, managerial merger efforts would have been so directed toward horizontal acquisitions that little time remained for exploring diversification acquisitions. This is not to imply that all subsequent merger efforts by the sample firms have been of the diversification genre. 189 On the contrary, for Continental Can acquired another glassware firm, Gamble—Skogmo maintained its strategy of acquiring retail merchandising firms, General Shoe (Genesco) made other purchases in shoes, Maremont in automotive parts, Automatic Canteen in vending machine operations, Continental Baking in baking, Gulf in petroleum, etc. Nevertheless the general tenor of the merger strategy of these firms has been to diversification. And it may well turn out that one of the principal effects of Section 7 on industrial structure has been and is to increase diversi— fication. Supporting this hypothesis is evidence presented by Mueller to the Senate Antitrust & Monopoly Subcommittee.l6 His data show that from 1948 to 1953, horizontal mergers comprised 31.0 per cent of the total universe of acquisitions Of "large" mining and manufacturing concerns.l7 By 1954 to 1959, this percentage dropped to 24.8 and continued, dropping to only 12.0 per cent for the period 1960 to 1964. On the other hand, product extension and conglomerate acqui- sition percentages rose from 51.8 per cent of the universe in 1948 to 1953 to 55.1 per cent in 1954 to 1959 to 64.1 4.18 per cent in 1960 to 196 From 1948 to 1964, conglomerate acquisitions were but 9.7 per cent of large acquisitions. By 1965 they were 18.3 per cent and, for the first half of 1966, 20.8 per cent.19 190 How one.views this trend depends on his View of-the large diversified firm as a threat to the vigor of compe— tition. If one says, with Stigler, that " . . . the exact mechanics by which the total power possessed by firms gets larger than the sum of the parts escapesme,"2O then diversification acquisitions will not command any concern. On the other hand, one who rates Justice Douglas as a jurist of the highest caliber and Henry Simons as an economist of considerable merit will be troubled by a law which seems to encourage this conglomeration. Section 7 and Aggrpgate Concentration The Rising Tide of Aggregate Concentration While any conclusions on Section 7 and its impact~ upon the managerial mind must remain somewhat tenuous, one thing is rather clear: if one intention of Congress in passing the Celler—Kefauver amendment was to stop the "rising tide of economic concentration," then Section 7 has- failed.21 For by whatever measure adopted as an indicator of aggregate concentration, the trend in the United States has;been clearly to that of greater control by the largest corporations.22 The recent report on Concentration Ratios in the manu- facturing sector prepared by the Bureau of the Census shows a steady increase from 1947 to 1963 in the aggregate concen_ tration of the 50, 100, 150, and 200 largest manufacturing 191 companies.23 Whereas the Share of value added in 1947 by the 200 largest manufacturing companies was 30 per cent, by 1963 this share had_increased to 41 per-cent. This represents an increase of 11 percentage points or, in a little over a decade and a half, a growth in aggregate concentration of 26.8 per cent. Mergers and Aggregate Concentration There is no doubt that mergers have contributed significantly to this increase in aggregate concentration. Of the 720 large acquisitions made between 1948 and 1964, the 200 largest manufacturing companies made 387 of them, absorbing over 65 per cent of the assets of all large companies acquired.during this time period.2L1 In a little more than a decade following the Celler-Kefauver amendment, 2,000 firms with assets of approximately $17.5 billion were acquired by the top 200 firms.25 Mueller estimated that at the rate of increase in aggregate concentration he found from the time of the Celler- Kefauver amendment to 1962, two—thirds of American.manu— facturing assets would be controlled by the 200 largest corporations by 1975.26 With increases of this magnitude, one can take little solace in the notion that "perhaps the increases would have been even greater in the absence of Section 7"-—just as there is little solace to be gained aboard a sinking I92 ship with the notion that the sinking could have taken place a day earlier. Moreover, there is no reason to 'believe that-merger activity will subside in the future. Indeed, the FTC recorded iplflé mergers in 1966. This was a slight.decline from the record year of-l965, but the number of "large" mergers increased for the fourth consecutive year.27 While Section 7 will squelch some horizontal and vertical acqui- sitions that would otherwise be consummated, acquisition strategy will not subside unless business activity subsides. Anyone interested in stopping either this trend in overall concentration or the high level of merger activity found in the American economy should be resigned to the fact that Section 7 will not do the job. Short of defla— tionary policy, which would be analagous to killing the patient to stop the disease, the most effective method of curbing mergers, and-no doubt the most efficient from an enforcement standpoint, would be a change in the tax laws which increased the relative attractivenesscn'internal 28 investment. The Future of Relief Only one conclusion can be drawn from the relief secured in early antimerger cases: it has not been a stunning success from the vantage-point of public policy. Though a close look has not been taken at relief efforts 193 other than those in this study, a cursory acquaintance with what has since happened permits these observations. The Judicial Front The judiciary still demonstrates its historical reluctance to whole-heartedly embrace the notion of strict (i.e., total) divestiture as being the logical relief in an antimerger case. In fact, one can safely predict that the Antitrust Division will continue to confront judges who will fail to grasp the relief principles of the duPont decision as outlined in Chapter II. Encourgging Developments with the Judiciary 5— However there are some encouraging developments on the judicial front. The Supreme Court's affirmation without opinion of the Alcoa-Cupples case might convince some judges that calling for the divestiture of post-acquisition additions and improvements is not a.far—fetched plea sounded only by rabid trust busters in the employ of the Antitrust 29 Division. The Supreme Court's per curiam approval here of the divestiture of post-acquisition properties might serve to instruct lower courts formulating relief decrees that after-acquired properties gpg a part of the fruits of the offense, that they should be, and legally can be, included in a divestiture order. The relief order in the Von's grocery case reflects this notion that the acquired 194 firm would have grown, in lieu of its being acquired, and therefore the relief order should allow for this would-have- taken-place growth.3O An Old Story Repeated Judicial reluctance to enact meaningful structural relief has been nowhere more apparent than in the anti— merger suit against El Paso Natural Gas.31 After being decided for the government at the Supreme Court and "divest— iture without delay" ordered in 1964, the case again came to the Supreme Court three years later, this time on the relief issue.32 The relief decree which El Paso had received in the lower court, following the Supreme Court's initial decision, was the cause of the second appeal to the Court. And the second appeal was not without good reason, for in Justice Douglas's words, the lower court's order was one that promises to perpetuate rather than terminate this unlawful merger, and that threatens to turn loose on the public a new company unable to maintain the competitive :fii: Egg: Picific Nogphwept iilied bggore ga ransac on 00 p ace. It is not at all encouraging to note that the Department of Justice was a party to this relief travesty, for the appeal came from private parties having a pecuniary interest in meaningful relief.3Ll But it is encouraging to note that the Supreme Court accepted this case for review, since relief decrees are ordinarily the domain of the lower. court. Such an acceptance should be indicative of the 195 importance the Supreme Court wants placed on the relief decree. The Court minced no words in rejecting the lower court's relief order. In fact Douglas took the unusual step of ordering a different District Judge to hear the case, a judicial slap—in—the—face whichlnight encourage others formulating relief not to mince words in their relief orders. Perhaps Douglas also should have removed those Justice Department lawyers who acquiesced to this order! One of the issues at law before the Supreme Court in El Paso II was the right of private plaintiffs to inter— vene in a relief order. The lower court had refused the private parties the right to object to any proposed relief formulation. Hopefully the Courtt overruling this refusal will be an important step in encouraging other private parties to intervene in unsatisfactory relief formulations. What is now needed is the right for private parties to intervene in the relief negotiations of consent settlements. The Administrative Front It is not inconceivable that the judiciary will have to abdicate its traditional role as the main bastion against structural relief; this role may be taken over by the Federal Trade Commission. The FTC's propensity to substitute a ban on future acquisitions for structural relief has been nOted in Chapter IV. In addition, the Commission has not 196 distinguished itself in securing anything approaching full divestiture in some of its other relief endeavors. For example, the FTC's attack of Procter & Gamble's acquisition of Folger was settled with Proctor & Gamble keeping four out of the five Folger plants. As Commis- sioner Jones said, dissenting from this partial divestiture: The consent order reaches only the periphery of the complaint. It allows Procter to keep four of the five acquired plants, thus perpetuating the major structural change caused by this merger. Instead of seeking divestiture, the order seeks to regulate, in'a quite direct manner and for a five year period, certain aspects of the conduct of Procter . ."35 Commissioner Reilly was briefer in his dissent. He concluded that the " . . . Commission thundered in the complaint and cheeped in the order."36 In a similar vein, the Commission's recent settlement of the Beatrice Foods case does not constitute structural- relief of the magnitude ordered in the Commission order against Beatrice. With the Commission again split, Commis- sioner Elman complained that the settlement fell short " . . . of the relief which the Commission, after extensive consideration, determined necessary."37 The Commission's Rulemaking Poligy One recent development to come out of the Commission, and one which could prove the most effective deterrent to mergers at the managerial planning stage, is its "close Watch" policy on certain industries. For example, in order 197 to keep close tabs on mergers in food distribution, every food retailer or food wholesaler with annual sales exceeding $10 million must notify the Commission at least sixty days prior to any merger with another food retailer or wholesaler. All portland cement manufacturers must likewise give at least sixty-day notice before acquiring any ready—mixed 38 concrete company. This thrust toward specific rules regarding the reporting of merger intentions cannot help but dampen some merger enthusiasm in the industries selected for this close surveillance. It is too early to evaluate this new direction in- antimerger enforcement. The method is a start in the rule- making procedure advocated by Commissioner Elman-of the FTC.39 Elman-wants enforcement strategy to turn from the normal case-by—case approach towards a strategy of examining specific industries; the intent being to devise guidelines on the legality of future mergers in these industries. Heavy emphasis upon the guidelines approach is not without its potential pitfalls. It is not inconceivable, given the slow turnings of the wheels of justice, that it will take a rash of mergers in an industry to precipitate an industry—wide investigation of the mergers. In addition, the specter of this enforcement strategy as being a step away from the Commission approval of mergersvfldj_loom up for some. FTC critics will be quick to predict the vacuous and vacillatory administration of such an enforcement 198 procedure. And their extrapolations, if based on past history of the commission form of regulation, will, unfor- tunately, not be without warrant. A Concluding Note on the Market as.a Force for Relief EXamining old relief decrees does not carry one to, ebullient heights on the-efficacyofSection 7 relief. Nor is-the probability high owaongress~passing new legislation to strengthen the hand of the government in enforcing the antimerger law. The future course that Section 7 enforcement will have to steer through the courts and the Commission is very bright for the prosecutors. But a no better prediction than the weatherman's "mixed" can be made for securing more meaningful relief. In light of this, what solace can the proponent of Section 7 enforcement take? He can find comfort in the fact that where the angels charged with formulating antimerger relief have feared to tread, the market mechanism has not always been so cowardly. Anyone doing research in the problem of relief as it relates to Section 7 violations cannot help but come away with renewed or strengthened faith in the market mechanism. Market conditions may so change during a prolonged adjudicatory proceeding that, at its conclusion, relief negotiations may seem almost unnecessary, or at least not nearly so pressing. 199 For example, in the Reynolds-Arrow acquisition, new domestic entry-into the industry which took place during the lengthy litigation, and the fierce new competition from foreign foil companies, brought about a steady decline in Arrow sales from 1960 to 1964 and effectively obliter- ated any potential market leverage Reynolds may have had from the acquisition.“0 While preparing its case before the Circuit Court in the Union Carbide-Visking acquisition, the General Counsel of the FTC advised the Commission to settle the case outside of Court by allowing Union Carbide to sell Visking to Texaco. Market forces were such that the Commission lawyers were skeptical of retaining their Commission victory on the appeal by Union Carbide. In this case the Commission had found a Section 7 violation largely on the prediction that Union Carbide would be able to drive non-integrated extruders of poly- ethylene film "to the wall" by lowering its own film prices. During the course of litigation, it became apparent, even three years after the merger, that such was not going to be the case. Union Carbide experienced a market share loss of ten percentage points in film resin and thirteen per— centage points in film production.“2 These losses came at the expense of gains by Union Carbide's competitors in film resins and film production, following the Visking acquisition. Perhaps this offers a new explanation for some of the weak 200 relief decrees—-name1y that industry conditions had some- times so changed that-the government became afraid to press too hard or else thought that structural relief was no longer as necessary as it one time may have been. The above is not in any way to be taken as favoring contentment with the status quo in antimerger relief. Nor can it serve as ammunition for those who might argue that anticompetitive mergers should be left to the market mechanism to undo. The fact still remains that where there is no meaningful cost to violating the antimerger law, the law will be broken. Relying only on the market mechanism to undo these mergers would offer would-be anticompetitive mergers the time and the opportunity to try and entrench their position against market forces. Undoubtedly, some would be successful. More than fifty years ago, Clark wrote that "only from a strife with the right kind of rules can the right kind of' M3 Business freedom must operate within a fitness emerge." framework of rules, lest the conduct of business destroy the basis upon which the freedom rests. Since free access by all to markets of more_than a few sellers is essential to preserve business freedom, a rule against the consum_ mation of anticompetitive mergers in indeed logical. 201 For this rule to be effective, the penalty for its violation must be stringent. The rule of quick, total structural relief needs to be followed if the incentive to consummate anticompetitive mergers is to minimized. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER VI 1Charles F. Phillips and George R. Hall, "Economic aneregal Aspects of Merger Litigation," University of Houston Business Review, 10 (Fall, 1963), p. 3. 2The Antitrust Climate, Mergers (New York: National Economic Research Associates, Inc., 1966). 3Willard Mueller, "Merger Policy in the Dairy Industry," an address before the 21st Annual Midwestern Milk Marketing Conference, Michigan State University, April 27, 1966, (mimeo). l4lbid., p. 4. 5Ibid., adapted from Appendix A, p. 33. 6Foremost Dgggies, Inc., FTC Docket 6495; National Dairy Products, FTC Docket 6651; Borden Co., FTC Docket 52; Beatirce Foods Corp., FTC Docket 6653. 7Mueller, op. cit., Appendix A. 8 Foremost Dairies, loc. cit., 60 FTC 1049 (1962). 9Mueller, op. cit., p. 30. 0These figures refer to cement acquisitions alone. Figures adapted from Economic Report on Mergers & Vertical Integration in the Cement Industry, A Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1966), Appendix D; hereafter cited as Cement Report. 11Permanente Cement Co., FTC Docket 7939; Diamond Alkali Co., FTC Docket 8572. 12 Cement Report, op. cit., Appendix D and p. 3. 13Ibid., adapted from Appendix E. 14 lbid., pp. 3—5. 15This is taken from records on company merger activity midway through 1966, gathered and compiled by the FTC. 202 203 16Testimony of Willard Mueller in U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & MonOpoly, Hearings, Economic Concentration, Part 2, 89th Cong., 1st Sess., March—April 1965, pp. 501—537. 17"Large" means assets of over $10 million. 18Adapted from Mueller, Hearings, p. 516. op. 19 Cite, Table 5, "Summary of Recent Merger Trends," Federal Trade Commission, 1966, Table 9 (mimeo . OGeorge Stigler, "Mergers and Preventive Antitrust Policy,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1 (November, 19555, p. 18 . Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 370 U.S. 294 at 317 (1962). 22 See testimonies of Gardiner C. Means, John Blair, and Willard Mueller in U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Hearings, Economic Concentration, Part 1, 88th Cong., 2nd Sess., July—September, 1964, pp. 17—19, 80-81, 204—207, and 120—123 respectively. 23 As measured by value added by manufacture. See U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, 1963 Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing Industry, Part I, 89th Cong., 2nd Sess., 1966, Table 1A, p. 24 Mueller, Hearings, Part 2, op. c1t., p. 518. 251bid. 26Ibid. , p. 519. 27HReport on 1966 Merger Activity," FTC, as reported in BNA ATRR 294: A—24—25. See for example: John Bossons, Kalman J. Cohen, and Samuel R. Reid, “Mergers for Whom—-Managers or Stock— holders?," Carnegie Institute of Technology Workshop on Capital Market Equilibrating Processes, Working Paper #14 (mimeo), April, 1966; J. F. Weston, The Role of Mergers in the Growth of Large Firms (Berkeley: Press, 1964 University of Cali- fornia Press, 1953), p. 104; Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (4th ed.; Chicago: University of Chicago ). pp. 130-132. 29Aluminum Company of America v. U. S., 382 U. S, 12 (1965). 204 30~ee BNA ATRR 291: A—l, judgment reprinted at x 1 3 3*U s. v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U s 651 (1964). 32See Cascade Natural Gas Corp El Paso Natural Gas Co., 386 U S . v. 129 (1967). 331bidu at 1141-“20 3MThe U.S. was an appellee in this case, ibid. at 137 and 141. Procter & Gamble Co., FTC Docket C 1169 Jones dissent, February 9, 1967, p. 2 (mimeo). Ibid., Reilly dissent, p 1. 37See WSJ, May 10, D. 5. 1967, p. 30 and ESQ, May 26 1967, This select1ve premerger notification has been accomplished, without anyadditionalCongressional legislation, under Section 6 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 717 (1914); 38 Stat. see Antitrust & Trade Re ulation Newsletter, 6(February 28,19675, 4 and BNA ATRR 289: A— 1— 3. 39Philip Elman, "The Need for Certainty and Predict— ability 1n the Application of the Merger Law," New York University Law Review, 40 (October, 1965), pp . 613-627 and ‘Comment Rulemaking Procedures in the FTC's Enforcement of the Merger Law, " Harvard Law Review, 78 Pt. 1 (December, 1964), pp. 385— 391. There is sympathy for this approach in the Department of Justice as well See address of Donald Turner,“Proposed Merger Guide11nes," in Current Antitrust Implications 1n the Merger Field, proceedings of the anti- trust committee Federal Bar Association (transcript Washington: Bureau of National Affairs S , September 17, 1965). Petition OfRespondent To Reopen Cause For New And Additional Evidence Or Alternatively For A Rehearing And For Modification Of Order Of January 21,1960," March 11, 1960 in Reynolds Metals Co., FTC Docket 7009. “Memorandum to the Commission from General Counsel, " March 26,1962 in Union Carbide Corp., FTC Docket 6826. 2Ibid., p. 6 433“ B Clark, The Control of Trusts (1914), as found in Walter Adams and Joel E Dirlam p. 201 , “Brown Shoe: In Step with Antitrust," Washington University Law Quarterly, 1963 (April 1663) p 15 BIBLIOGRAPHY 205 BIBLIOGRAPHY Books Alberts, William, and Segall, Joel (eds.).' The Corporate Merger. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1966. Bain, Joe S. Industrial Organization. New York: Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1959. Boulding, Kenneth E., and Spivey, William A. (eds.). Linear Prggrammipg and the Theory of the Firm. New York: The Macmillan Co., 1960. Brandeis, Louis D. The Curse of Bignese. O. K. Fraenkel (ed.). New York: The Viking Press, 1935. Burns, Joseph. A Study of the Antitrust,Laws. New York: Central Book Co., 1958.» ' Clark, John B. The Control of Trusts. New York: The Macmillan Co., 1902. Conference of the Universities--National-Bureau Committee for Economic Research. Business Concentration and Price Polipy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1955. Cox, Reavis. Competition in the American Tobacco Industry, 1911—1932. New York: Columbia University Press, 1933. Dewey, Donald. MonOpoly in Economics and Law. Chicago: Rand McNally & Company, 1959. Friedman, Milton. Cgpitalism & Freedom. 4th ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964. . Price Theory. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Co., 1962. IT Hale, George E., and Hale, Rosemary D. Market Power: Size and Shape under the Sherman Act. Boston: Little,5Brown and Company, 1958. Haley, B. F. (ed.). A Survey of Contemporapy Economics, Vol.1II. Homewood, Ill: R. D. Irwin, 1952. 206 207 Heflebower, Richard B., and Stocking, George (eds.). A. E. A. Readings in Industrial Organization and PublicPolicy. Homewood, 111.: R. D. Irwin, 1958. Jones, Eliot. The Trust Problem in the United States. New York: The Macmillan Co., 1923. 5‘ Josephson, Matthew. The Robber Barons, 1962 ed. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World Inc., 1962. Kaysen, Carl. United States v. United Shoe Machinery Copporation. ‘Cambridge: Harvard University PreSs, 1956. Kaysen, Carl, and Turner, Donald F. Antitrust Policy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1959. Mace, Myles L., and Montgomery, George G. Management Problems of Copporate Acqpisitions. Boston: Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1962. Martin, David D. Mergprs and the Clayton Act. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1959. Massell, Mark S. Competition and Monqpoly. New York: Doubleday & Company, 1964. McCarthy, George D. Acquisitions and Mergers. New York: The Ronald Press Co. ,1963. Mund, Vernon. Government & Business. 4th ed. New York: Harper & Row, 1965 Nelson, Ralph L. Merger Movements in American Industry, 1895-1956. Princeton: ‘Princeton University. Press, 1959. Penrose, Edith. The Thegry of the Growth of the Firm. New York: Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1959.65‘ Weinberg, M. A. Take—Overs and Amalgamations. London: Sweet & Maxwell, 1963. Weston, J. Fred. The Role of Mergers in the Growth of Large Firms. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1953. 208 Articles and Periodicals Adams, Walter. "Dissolution, Divorcement, Divestiture: The Pyrrhic Victories of Antitrust," Indiana Law Journal, 27 (Fall, 1951), pp. 1—37. '— . "The Aluminum Case: Legal Victory--Economic Defeat," American Economic Review, 41 (December, 1951), pp. 915-922. Adams, Walter, and Dirlam, Joel E. "Brown_Shoe: In Step with Antitrust," Washipgton Universipy Law Quarterly, 1963 (April, 1963), pp. 158-173. . "Steel Imports and Vertical Oligopoly Power," American Economic-Review, 54 (September, 1964), pp. 626-655. Adelman, M. A. "Small Business--A Matter of Definition," American Bar Associationi Section of Antitrust Law Proceedinge, 16 (April, 1960), pp. 18-32. Baumol, William. "On the Theory of the Expansion of the Firm," American Economic-Review, 52 (December, Berge, Wendell. "Some Problems in the Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws," Michigan Law Review, 38 (February, 1940), pp. 462-478. "Big get Bigger: Bud, Schlitz and Pabst pull ahead," Printers' Ink, February 10, 1967, pp. 11—19. Bok, Derek C. "Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics," Harvard Law Review, 74 (December, 1960), pp. 226—355. Brown, H. Templeton. "Injunctions and Divestiture," American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust, Law Proceedings, 10 (August, 19547, pp. 129—141. Carter, William A. "The Clayton Act, Original Section 7: Reexamination and Reappraisal," Antitrust Bulletin, 8 (March-April, 1963), pp. 187-225. Cock, Donald. "Acquisition of stock tending to create monopoly—.Equitable decree," Osgoode Hall Law Journal, 2 (April, 1960), pp. 154—158. "Comment, Aspects of Divestiture as an Antitrust Remedy," Fordham Law Reviep, 32 (October, 1963), pp. 135—146. 209 Cook, Paul W. "Merger Law and Big Business:- A Look Ahead," New York University Law Review, 40 (October, 1965), pp. 710—724. Daly, Thomas F. "Current Trends in Relief under Clayton. Act Section 7," Dickinson Law Review, 70 (Fall, 1965)) pp' l-u9o Day, Richard E. "Conglomerate Mergers and 'The.Curse of Bigness,'" North Carolina Law Review, 42 (April, Decker, R. K., "The Civil Investigative Demand," Kentucky Law Journal, 51 (Spring, 1963), pp. 449-465. Dewey, Donald. "Romance and Realism in Antitrust Policy," Journalof Political Economy, 63 (April, 1955), ppo 93-1020 I Duke, Robert D. "Scope of Relief under Section 7 of the Clayton Act," Columbia Law Review, 63 (November, 1963), pp. 1192—1211. Dulin, Jacques M. "Availability of Civil Demand to Investigate Preposed Acquisition," George Washington Law Review, 34 (October, 1965), pp. 150-158. ’ Elman, Philip. "Rulemaking Procedures in the FTC's Enforcement of the Merger Law," Harvard Law Review, 78 (December,1964), pp. 385-391. . "The Need for Certainty and Predictability in the Application of the Merger Law," New York University Law Review, 40 (October, 1965), pp. 613-627. Fish, Sidney. "Antitrust Landmark Cases," Journal of Commerce, June 21, 1965, p. 3. "Government Agency Profile—-the FTC," Mergers & Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Spring, 1966), pp. 76-780 Hale, George E. "Trust Dissolution: Atomizing Business Units ovaonopolistic Size," Columbia Law Review, 40 (April, 1940), pp. 615-632. Handler, Milton. "Recent Antitrust Developments," Michigan Law Review, 63 (November, 1964), pp. 59-94. Handler, Milton, and Robinson, Stanley D. "A Decade of Administration of the Celler—Kefauver Act," Columbia Law Review, 61 (April, 1961),pp. 629—679. 210 Harbeson, Robert W. "The Clayton Act: Sleeping Giant of Antitrust?" American Economic Review, 48 (March, 1958), ppo 92-104. ' Harwood, James. "The Mystique of Antitrust," Mergers-& Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Fall, 1965), p0 350 Heflebower, R. B. "Corporate Mergers: Policy and Economic Analysis," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 77 (November, 1963), pp. 537-558. "In Brief," Mergers & Acquisitions: The Journal of Corporate Venture, 1 (Winter, 1966), pp. 7-8. Kerr, William T. "Divestiture of illegally held Assets: Observations on its Scope, Objective, and Limitations," Michigan Law Review, 64 (June, 1966), pp. 1574-1599. Lewyn, Thomas M., and Mann, Stephen. "Some Thoughts on Policy and Enforcement of Section 7 of the Clayton Act," American Bar Association Journal, 50 (February, 1964), pp. 154-157» Machlup, Fritz. "Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial," American Economic ReV1ew, 57 (March, 1967), pp. 1-33. Manne, Henry G. "Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control," Journal of Political Economy, 73 (April, 1965), pp. 110—120. Marcus Philip. "The Impact on Business of Antitrust Decrees," Vanderbilt Law Review, 11 (March, 1958), pp» 303-330. Markham, Jesse. "Merger Policy under the new Section 7: A six year Appraisal," Virginia Law Rev1ew, 43 (May, 1957). pp. 489-528. "The Brown Case and the New Antimerger Martin, David. 1963) 3 Policy," American Economic Review, 53 (June, pp. 340-358. McGuire, J. W., Chiu, J. S. Y., and Elbing, A. U. " American "Executive Incomes Sales and Profits, . Economic Review, 52-(September, 1962), pp. 751—761. Nicholls, W. H. "The Tobacco Case of 1946," American Economic Review Proceedinge, 39 (May, 19 9 , pp. 284—296. 211 Noall, Roger, and Chase, Troxell D. "Tax Aspects of Antitrust Proceedings,"-Tax Law Review, 18 (January, 1963), pp. 213—250. 'Wbte,Ayailability of Divestiture in Private Litigation aS;a Remedy for Violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act," Minnesota Law Review, 49 (December, 1964), pp. 267-283.‘ "Note, Clayton Act, Section 7 Remedies," Tulane_Law Review, 34 (February, 1960), pp. 402-409. "Note, Preliminaryifiuunctions and the Enforcement of Section 7 of the Clayton Act," New York University 'Law Review, 40 (October, 1965) pp. 771-784. ' "Note, Preliminary Relief for the Government under Section 7 of the Clayton Act," Harvard Law Review, 79 (December, 1965), pp. 391-406. "Note, Section 7 of the Clayton Act: A Legislative History," Columbia Law Review, 52 (June, 1952), pp. 766-781. Phillips, Charles F., and Hall, George R. "Economic and~ Legal Aspects ofMerger Litigation," University of Houston Business Review, 10 (Fall, 1963), pp. 1+9B. Saving, T. R. "Estimation of Optimum Size by the Survivor. Technique," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75 (November, 1961), pp. 569-607» Schwartz, Louis B. "New Approaches to the Control of Oligopoly," University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 109 (November, 1960), pp. 31-53.’ Siegel, David D. "The Antitrust Civil Process Act: The Attorney General's Preaction Key to Company Files," Villanova Law Review, 10 (Spring, 1965), pp. 413—434. Siegel, Stanley. "When-Corporations Divide: A Statutory and Financial Analysis," Harvard Law ReView, 79 (January, 1966), pp.-534-570. Stepanek, Michael. "Implied Powers of Federal Agencies to order Divestiture," Notre Dame Lawyer, 34 (August, 1964), pp. 581—593. "The Economies of Scale," Journal of Sti . gler, George 1958), pp. 54-71. Law and Economics, 1 (October, 212 Stigler, George. "Mergers and Preventive Antitrust Policy," University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 104 (November, 19537, pp. 176—184. "Monopoly and Oligopoly by Merger," American Economic Review Proceedings, 40 (May, 19505, pp. 23—34. Timberg, Sigmund. "Equitable Relief under the Sherman Act," University of Illinois Law Forum, 1950 (Winter, 1950), pp. 629—658.‘ Whitney, Simon N. "Mergers, Conglomerates, and Oligopolies: A Widening of Antitrust Targets," Rutgers Law Review, 21 (Winter, 1967), pp. 187_261, Whitney, Simon N. "Vertical Disintegration in the Motion Picture Industry," American Economic Review Proceedings, 45 (May, 1955), pp. 991-498. Legal Cases ABC Vending Corp., In the matter of. FTC Docket 7652. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1963—1965), Par. l7,lO9—-stipulated order requiring divestiture. American Bakeries, In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C—llll (196677as found in CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-1967), par. 17,605, Arrow—Hart & Hegeman Electric Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 291 U.S. 587 (1934). *Automatic Canteen Co. of America, In the matter of. FTC Docket 6820. Beatrice Foods Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6653. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-1967), Par. l7,244——Opinion of Commission. Ibid. at Par. l7,398——Final order of divestiture. Ibid. at Par. l7,949-—Proposed consent order modifying above divestiture order. Borden Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6652. 62 FTC 130 (1963). *Brillo Mfg. Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6557. *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional information. 213 Broadway Hale Stores, Inc., In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C—1057 (1966) as found in CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-1967), Par. 17,502. Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 370 U.S. 294 (1962). Cascade Natural Gas Corp. v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 386 U.S. 129 (1967). Consolidated Foods,gIn the matter of. FTC Docket 7000. 62 FTC 929 (19587—-Opinion of Commission. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1961—1963), Par. I6:362-—Final Order on relief. 329 F. 2d 623 (1964)——reversing Commission. 380 U.S. 592 (l965)——Circuit Court reversed by Supreme Court. *Continental Baking Cog; In the matter of. FTC Docket 7880. Crane Co. V. Briggs Mfg. Co., 280 F. 2d 747 (1960). *Crown Zellerbach, In the matter of. FTC Docket 6180. Diamond Alkali, In the matter of. FTC Docket 8572. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder l965—1967),Par. l7,36l—-Opinion of the Commission of October, 1965. *Diamond Crystal Salt Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 7 Erie Sand & Gravel Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6670. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (ETC Transfer Binder 1959-1960), Par. 28;358-—Opinion of Commission and order of divestiture of October, 1959. Erie Sand & Gravel Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 291 F. 2d 279 (l96lS——Circuit Court remand to FTC for addi— tional evidence. 60 FTC 19 (1962)-—Commission dismissal of complaint. *Farm Journal, Inc., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6388. Federal Trade Commission v. Dean Foods Company, 356 F. 2d 1 l9 , reversed 384 U.S. 597 (1966). FEderal Trade Commission V. Eastman Kodak Co., 274 U.S. I9 1927 . *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional information. 214 Federal Trade Commission v. International Paper Co., 241 F. 2d 372 (1956). Foremost Dairies, In the matter of. FTC Docket 6495. 60 FTC 944 (1962). Georgia Pacific Corp., In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C-751 (1964) as found in CCH Trade Regglation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1963—1965), Par. 1 ,929. *Gulf Oil Corporation, In the matter of. FTC Docket 6689. Hamilton Watch Co. v. Benrus Watch Co., 206 F. Supp. 73 1953 . Hartford Empire v. U.S., 324 U.S. 570 (1945). *Hooker Chemical Corp., In the matter of. FTC Docket 8034. *International Paper Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6676. International Salt Co. v. U.S., 332 U.S. 392 (1947), *Leslie Salt Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 8220. May Department Stores Co., In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C-1105 (1966) as found in CCH Trade RegulatiOn Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-1967), Par. 17,684, *Minnesota Mining & Mfg. Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 7973. *National Dairy Products Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6651. *National Sugar Refining Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6852. National Tea Co., In the matter of. FTC Docekt 7453. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder “— 1965—1967), Par. l7,463-—Opinion of the Commission and Order of March, 1966. ‘1 . *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional 1nformation. 215 Permanente Cement Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 7939. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-1967), Par. l7,222——Consent order requiring divestiture of March, 1965. Ibid. at Par. 17,613-- Order approving divestiture of July, 1966. Pillsbury Mills Inc.,gIn the matter of. FTC Docket 6000. 57 FTC 1414'(l960)--Fina1 Order of divestiture. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965;1967), Par. l7,484—-Final Order of dismissal. Procter & Gamble Co., In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C—1169 (1967) as found in CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965—1967), Par. 17,858. *Reynolds Metals Co., In the mptter of. FTC Docket 7009. *Scott Paper Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6559. *Scovill Mfg. Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6527. *Simpson Timber Co., In the matter of. FTC Docket 7713. *Spalding, A. G. & Bros., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6478. Thatcher Mf . Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 272 U.S. 554 (1926). Timken Roller Bearing Co. v. U.S., 341 U.S. 593 (1951). *Union Bag & Paper Corp., In the matter of. FTC Docket 639l. *Union Carbide Corp., In the matter of. FTC Docket 6826. *The Vendo Company, In the matter of. FTC Docket 6646. U. —_ v. Aluminum Company of America, 91 F. Supp. 333 (1950), S. H;§- v. Aluminum Company of America and Rome Cable Corp. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1512. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,727——decision on temporary relief. 214 F. Supp. 501 (1963)—-Decision dis— missing complaint. 377 U.S. 271 (l964)——reversed by Supreme Court. . *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional information. 216 Egg. v. Aluminum Company of America and Cupples Products Cor . Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1607. 247 F. Supp. 308 (l962)——preliminary injunction. 247 F. Supp. 316 (l964)--Final Judgment. 382 U.S. l2 (l965)—-aff'd by Supreme Court. U.S. v. American Can Co., 1951 CCH Trade;Cases, Par. 62,679. “U.S. v. American Cyanamid Company. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1565. *U.S. v. American Radiator and Standard Sanitary. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1275. U.S. v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106 (1911). *U.S. V. Anheuser—Buschngnc. Antitrust Division Blue Book No 1421. a: 'C.‘ w v. Bethlehem Steel Corporation. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1313. *U.S. v. Brown Shoe Co., Inc. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1266. I U.S. v. Chrysler Corp. & Mack Trucks, 232 F. Supp. 651 (1964). *U.S. v. Continental Can Company. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1310. CI [/1 r . v. Crescent Amusement Co., 323 U.S. 173 (1944). C." U) r v.Crocker-Anglo National Bank, 1963 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,934. ' *U.S. v. Diebold Incorporated. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1471. ELS. v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377 (1956). ggs. v. E. 1. duPont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586 (1957). ELS. v. E. I. duPont de Nemours & Co., 366 U.S. 315 (1961). ELS. v. El Paso Natural Gas. Co., 376 U.S. 651 (1964). *Sample case. See Appendix A. for additional information. 217 U.S. v. Food Machinepy Corp. & American Viscose Corp., 1963 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,826: *U.S. v. Gamble—Skogmo, Inc. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1513. ' U.S. v. General Electric Co., 115 F. Supp. 835 (1953). *U.S. v. General Shoe Corporation. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1220. C.‘ .S. v. Gimbel Brothers Inc., 202 F. Supp. 779 (1962). C.‘ S. v. Greater Buffalo Press, Incgg et al., 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,380. ‘ *U.S. v. The Hertz Corp. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1444. *U.S. v. Hilton Hotels Corporation. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1229. UL§. v. Ingersoll Rand Co., 218 F. Supp. 530 (1963), aff'd 320 F. 2d. 509 (1963). * 'C‘. (D V. Jerrold Electronics Corp. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1318. *U.S. v. Lucky Lager Brewing Compa_y. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1370. *U.S. v. Maremont Automotive Products. Antitrust Division Blue BOok No. 1543. U.S. v. Minute Maid Corp. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1253. 1955 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,13l-— Consent Decree. U.S. v. National Alfalfa Dehydrating and Milling Company. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1398. 1963 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,665--Consent decree. U.S. v. National Homes Cogp. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1485. 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,533-— Consent decree. U.S. v. Northern Securities Co., 193 U.S. 197 (1904). ‘_F *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional information. 218 *U.S. v. Owens-Illinois Glass Company. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1310. .S. v. Pabst Brewing Company, 384 U.S. 546 (1966). .s. v. Philadelphia National Bank. 374 U.S. 321 (1963). .S. v. Pullman Co., 50 F. Supp. 123 (1943). 3|: .8. v. Ryder System, Inc. Antitrust Division-Blue Book No. 1564. *U.S. v. Schenley Industries, Inc. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 12147 .S. V. Standard Oil Co. of N. J., 221 U.S. 71 (1911). C} . . v. Standard Oil Co. of N. J., 1965 CCH Trade Cases;'Par. 71,503. *U.S. v. Standard Oil Company of Ohio. Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1490. ELS. v. Third National Bank of Nashville, 1964 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 71,209. ' U.S. v. United Shoe Machinery Co., 110 F. Supp. 295 (1953). U.S v. Von's Grocery Co., 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,698. HL§. V. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270 (1966). Winn-Dixie Stores, Inc., In the matter of. FTC Consent Order C-1110 (1966) as found in CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1965-196“), Par. 17,694. Reports, Papers, and Addresses American Bar Association. Merger Case Digest. Revised, January, 1964. American Management Association. Lega1,_Financia1, and’ Tax Aspects of Mergers and Acquisitions. Financial Management Series #114. New York: American Management Association, 1957. *Sample case. See Appendix A for additional information. 219 Bock, Betty. Mergers and Markets, Studies in Business Economics No. 85. New York:\ The National Industrial Conference Board, July, 1964. Book, Betty. Mergers and Markets, Studies in Business Economics No. 93. New York: The National Industrial Conference Board, 1966. Bossons, John, Cohen, Kalman J., and Reid, Samuel R. Mergers for Whom-~Managers or Stockholders? Working Paper No. 14, Carnegie Institute of Technology Workshop on Capital Market Equilibrating Processes, April, 1966. Cohen, Kalman J., and Reid, Samuel R. Bank Mergers for Whom-~Managers, Stockholders, or the 'Public'? Working Paper No. 10, Carnegie Institute of Technology Workshop on Capital Market Equili— brating Processes, April, 1966. Dallstream, Andrew J. Report and Recommendations of Andrew J. Dallstream, Amicus Curiae with respect to the; Interests of Stockholders of E. I. duPont de Nemours, and Company. (In U. S. v. duPont et al., Civil Action No. 49 C 1071, U. S. D. C. for N. I11.) August, 1958). Diversification Institute, affiliated with Boni, Watkins, Jason & Co., Inc. A Report on Results of a Survey . of Business Qpinion regarding Premerger Notification Legislation. New York, nd. Federal Bar Association, Antitrust Committee. "Proposed Merger Guidelines," a transcript of a panel dis— cussion at the annual meeting, Chicago, Illinois, September 17, 1965, in: Current Antitrust Implica— tions in the Merger Field. Washington: Bureau of National Affairs. Goldberg, Milton S. The Consent Decree: Its Formulations and Use, Occasional Paper No. 8} E. Lansing: Michigan State University Bureau of Business & Economic Research, 1962. Mueller, Willard F. "Merger Policy in the Dairy Industry," address before the 2lst Annual Midwestern Milk Marketing Conference, Michigan State University, April 27, 1966. National Economic Research Associates, Inc. The Antitrust Climate: Mergers. New York, 1966. Perkins, George. "A Constructive Suggestion," address before Chamber-of Commerce, Youngstown, Ohio, December 4, 1911 (pamphlet). 220 Public Documents Annual Report of the Attorney General of the United States. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1964. Economic Report(s) of the President. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1956-1960. Federal Trade Commission. Economic Report on Mergers & Vertical Integration in the Cement Industry. washington, D.C., April, 1966. Federal Trade Commission. Report on Corporate Mergers- and Acquisitions, 1955. Federal Trade Commission. "Summary of Recent Merger Trends," (mimeo), 1966. Hamilton, Walton, and Till, Irene. Antitrust in Action, TNEC Monograph No. 16. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1941. Handler, Milton. A Study of the Enforcement of the Federal Antitrust Laws, TNEC Monograph No. 38. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1941. Report of the Attorney_General's National Committee to Study the Antitrust LaWs. Washington; U.S. Government Printing Office, 1955. U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. =Administered Prices: ‘A Compendium on Public Policy. '88th Cong., lst. Sess., 1963. ’ U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. Hearings, Authorization for Department of Justice to make Demand:fianvidence.in Civil Antitrust Investigations. 87th Cong., lst. Sess., June, 1961. U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. Hearings, Economic Concentration, Part 1, 88th Cong., 2nd Sess.: July—September, 1964. U.S. Senate, S ommittee_on Antitrust & MonOpoly, Hearings, Economic Concentration. Part 2, 89th Cong., lst Sess., March-April, 1965. U.S.-Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & MonOpoly. ' Hearings, Legislation affecting Corporate Mergers. 84th Cong., 2nd Sess., May-June, 1956. 221 U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. Hearings, Legislation affecting Sections 7, 11, and 15 of the Clayton Act. 785th Cong., 2nd sess., April-May, 1958. U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. Hearings, Premergpr Notification Legislation. 86th Cong., 1stSess., 1959. U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly. Report, COrporate Mepgers and Acquisitions. 85th Cong., lst Sess, March, 1957. U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust & Monopoly, Report, 1963 Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing, InduStry. 89th Cong., 2nd Sess., 1966. ADDENDUM TO BIBLIOGRAPHY There are certain sources to which I am certainly indebted but they are too numerous for individual listing. I mention them in a collective manner in this addendum. The Wall Street Journal provided additional information on corporate merger activity, the relief problem, as well- as the data often needed to compute acquisition prices in the case of stock exchanges. My debt to the Bureau of National Affairs Antitrust & Trade Regulation Report, including its "Analysis"7section, is substantial; almost every issue contained information enabling me to keep abreast of antimerger developments. Various issues of Management Reports Inc. Antitrust and Trade Regulation Newsletter were also helpful. The Annual Reports, SEC Prospectuses, and press releases of the acquiring and~ acquired-corporations were also read and proved useful in identifying the activities and properties of these companies or verifying data on acquisition dates, prices, etc. Moody's Industrial Manual was also an important source in this regard. Finally, this thesis would not have been possible . without the use of the Pleadipg Files made available to me (at the Antitrust Division and the Docket Files and Compliance Reports made available to me at the Federal Trade Commission. I have perused these files and reports for all the cases in my merger sample plus several others.* While I have cited much of the published legal material relating to these cases in either this bibliography or Appendix A, there are numerous sources, particularly the legal briefs and compliance reports upon which I relied heavily in my research, which are not aublished but are available in the aforementioned Files. [one of the sources of this nature are herein specifically ited. Whenever a specific brief, report, or memorandum was entioned in the text, the document was found in the File or that particular case. . fiv *ABC Vending, Alcoa-Cupples, Alcoa—Rome, Borden, olidated Foods, Diamond Alkali, Erie Sand & Gravel, nost, Minute Maid, National Alfalfa, National Homes, ?illsbury. 222 APPENDICES APPENDIX A THE SAMPLE CASES 224 225 AMERICAN CYANAMID CO.-FORMICA CO. AND PANELYTE DIVISION OF ST. REGIS PAPER CO. Complaint filed October 5, 1960, amended October 13, 1960, to drop the complaint against-Panelyte; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1565. Disposed of by Consent-Decree of August 4, 1964. 1964 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 71, 166. Date of merger(s): Formica Co. acquired in April, 1956; Panelyte in August, 1958. Relief-Ordered a. Divestiture within 2 years of American Cyanamid's Willow Island melamine-producingfacilities (or the option, not taken, of leasing same for a S-year period to a lessee, the lessee agreeing to construct a new melamine plant within 5 years-and to supply American Cyanamid's domestic melamine needs during the lease period). b. 20 year ban on acquisitions of firms engaged in ~manufacture or sale of dicy, melamine, melamine resins, laminates or their end products without government approval. c._ Divestiture of the Willow Island plant to include technical assistance from American Cyanamid as well as employment rights to Willow Island personnel. d.' 10 year restriction on American's expansion of its melamine capacity to a maximum of 30 million 1bs./yr. and a restriction of American's domestic production of melamine to 30 million 1bs./yr. This restriction to be rescinded should Willow Island“ or U.S. melamine capacitybe increased by 25 million 1bs./yr., over and above American Cyanamid's capacity at time of divestiture. e. American must purchase, at the acquirer's option, at least 50% of its outside melamine requirements from the acquirer, for a lO—year period, at prevailing market prices. 226 f. 10-year buying requirement imposed on American to purchase, after divestiture of Willow Island, melamine from other producers in amounts equivalent to its requirements for melamine used in the manu- facture of laminates. g. Patent licensing provisions and other miscellaneous marketing orders. Special Comment American Cyanamid negotiated an order requiring divest- iture of properties other than those cited in the com-. plaint as violating Section 7. The rationale behind- this substitution of assets to be divested apparently ~goes something like this: the restraint lies in vertical foreclosure, with American Cyanamid being the sole domestic seller of melamine and Formica being a sub— stantial buyer of melamine,for use in making its laminated products; the restraint can be alleviated by relief- at either end of the vertical chain. The government (rightly) argued that allowing the Formica acquisition to stand would discourage entry into both melamine and laminated products since, at the time the complaint, American Cyanamid was the sole domestic producer of melamine for sale and, its owning both Formica and Panelyte, would decrease the selling alternatives of a new melamne producer. And this situation would certainly cause any potential independent producer of laminated' products to have_qua1ms about his source of melamine resins. ' ‘ The divestiture order is lacking in itself due to the terribly complex nature of the marketing order which accompanies the structural relief. This order will either not be enforced or, if enforced, will involve the government in watchdog activities that are repuge nant to the concept of antitrust. There also is little doubt that American was-eager to substitute the Willow Island facilities for the divestiture of Formica. Subsequent to the complaint, the threat of new entry into melamine became apparent. In fact, by 1966, there ' were eight producers selling melamine in the U.S. according to.the 1967 Chemical Buyers Guide. Melamine, a homogeneous product with a declininggrowth rate, also faces stiff competition from overseas capacity-—. in fact there seems little doubt that a better margin is to be made on a branded differentiated product like Formica (see "Chemical Profile: Melamine" in Oil, Paint and Drug-Reporter, Chemical Profiles. New York: Schnell Publishing 00.). In 1960, the year of the 227 complaint, American opened a ppw_melamine plant using "an improved process for the production of melamine" at Wallingford, Conn. (see their 1959 Annual Report, p. 5). This is further reason for American Cyanamid's trying to preserve the Formica acquisition at the eXpense of their Willow Island facilities. Forcing American to divest Formica would have left American as a strong competitor in laminated products and would have eliminated most of the complex marketing order. The Willow Island plant was sold in November, 1964, to the Fisher Chemical Company and operates as the Fisher Melamine Corp. with headquarters in New York City. While Fisher is a satisfactory buyer of the melamine plant, this divestiture probably accom- plishes little. It is unfortunate that the divestiture substitution was allowed and the resultant marketing order was instituted. The relief is DEFICIENT. 228 AMERICAN RADIATOR AND STANDARD SANITARY- MULLINS MANUFACTURING CO. Complaint filed March 30, 1956; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1275. Disposed of by Consent Decree of September 20, 1960. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,810. Date of merger: January, 1956. Relief-Ordered a. 5-year ban on acquisitions of any manufacturer or distributor of plumbing fixtures without government approval. b. Divestiture of its Youngstown Kitchen division (formerly Mullins) plants at Salem and Warren, Ohio, including improvements at Warren, Ohio. c. Divestiture of the Liberty Plant at Warren, Ohio, and Plant No. 3 at Salem, Ohio, acquired from Mullins Mfg. Co. d. Divestiture of stock interest in In—Sink-Erator. lSpecial Comment Divestiture of the bulk of the assets formerly consti- tuting Mullins took place in November, 1961, to an independent group of purchasers headed by Leonard Morey. The name of the new company is Mullins Mfg. Co. Since Mullins cost American Radiator $36 million and ' was divested for $6.2 million, obviously the "new" Mullins was not the size of its former self. But American suffered heavy losses on the acquisition of Mullins and its value had declined accordingly. Divestiture resulting in a new and independent -Mullins is SUCCESSFUL relief. 229 ANHEUSER-BUSCH, INC.-MIAMI BREWERY OF AMERICAN BREWING CO. Complaint filed October 30, 1958; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1421. Disposed of by Consent Decree of January 11, 1960. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,599. Date of merger: February, 1958. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of the Miami brewery, with improvements, in such manner that the.brewery be re-established -as an Operating competitor in the Florida market. b. Seemingly a permanent ban on Florida brewery acquisitions.‘ c. 5-year ban on acquisitions in brewing without government approval. d. Ban on selling Anheuser's "popular price" beer in Miami area until 6 months after divestiture. Special Comment The Miami brewery was sold in October, 1961, to National Brewing Co., Baltimore, Maryland, a regional brewing company which is not a member of the nation's 10 largest brewers. National was #16 in 1965 and 1966 with 1.9% of the national market according to Printers' Ink (Feb. 10, 1967, p. 12). Since National's regional efforts in the marketing of its beer were not ~in the scuth, National is an acceptable buyer for the divested brewery. A case of SUFFICIENT relief. 230 AUTOMATIC CANTEEN CO. OF AMERICA- ROWE CORP. Complaint filed June 14, 1957; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6820. I Disposed of by Consent Order of June 23, 1958. 54 FTC 1831 (1958). Date of merger: December, 1954. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within one year of 13 Rowe subsidiaries (local vending machine operators in areas also served by Automatic Canteen). b. lO-year ban on future acquisitions of any vending- machine manufacturer in competition with vending machines produced by Automatic Canteen. c. lO-year marketing requirement that Automatic offer for sale at least 50% of its annual production of each type of vending machine it manufactures to vendors.other than its own. Special Comment In this case Automatic Canteen was allowed to keep that part of RoWe it really wanted—~namely its facilities for manufacturing vending machines.~ Automatic, the. nation's largest purchaser and operator of vending~ machines, had no manufacturing facilities prior to . acquiring Rowe, the latter producing 12% of the nation's~ machines at the time of the complaint. The-l3 local operators to be divested were an ancillary part of the acquisition-—indeed since the consent order, Automatic has acquired more than that number of the same sort of operators. The 13 subsidiaries and their dates of divestiture are as follows: 231 Rowe Service Co., Inc. Los Angeles September, 1958 California Cigarette Concession Los Angeles September, 1958 Rowe Cigarette Service San Diego January, 1959 San Jose Cigarette Service San Jose May, 1959 Cigarette Service Co. Denver September, 1959 Wagg Cigarette Service Louisville November, 1959 Syracuse Cigarette Service Syracuse July, 1959 Ace Wheeling Cigarette Wheeling, W. Va. October, 1958 Allegheny Cigarette Service Pittsburgh June, 1959 AceCigarette Service. Brackenridge, Pa. June, 1959 Acme Cigarette Service Greensburg, Pa. June, 1959 Acorn Cigarette Service Aliquippa, Pa. June: 1959 Uniontown Cigarette Service Uniontown, Pa. June. 1959 The total price received-byAutomatic in the divestiture of the 13 vendors was-less than $2 million as compared to the acquisition price of over $8 million. To: "offset" the vertical part of the acquisition, the government agreed to a marketing order to "protect" the non-integrated vending machine operators for 10 years. This-is no substitute for structural relief. Consequently, the case results in UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 232 BETHLEHEM STEEL CORPORATION—THE YOUNGSTOWN SHEET AND TUBE COMPANY Complaint filed December 12, 1956, Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1313. Disposed of by Final Judgment prohibiting the merger and holding it to be unlawful, December 19, 1958. 168 F. Supp. 576 (l958)--Decision of DistrictCourt. Date of merger: Merger consummated on paper only with the stock distribution and asset commingling never having taken place. Relief Ordered a. lknunction against completing the merger. Special Comment By stOpping this merger in its incipiency, no relief problems resulted. A case of SUCCESSFUL relief. 233 BRILLO MFG. CO.-WILLIAMS co. Complaint filed May 22, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6557. Disposed of by Opinion of the Commission finding Section 7 violation on July 31, 1963; Final Order on relief, January 17, 1964. 56 FTC 1672 (1960——Commission Order vacating Hearing Examiner's Initial Decision and Order and remanding case to Examiner for further proceedings. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 1963—1965), Par. l6,543—-Opinion of the Commission, July 31, 1963. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter, (FTC Trade Binder 1963—1965), Par. l6,746-—Fina1 Order on relief. Date of merger: July, 1955. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within one year of all patents, trade— marks, trade names, and customer lists formerly belonging to Williams Co. 1 b. Brillo is allowed to retain the manufacturing facilities and fixed assets of Williams but is not to use them in the manufacture of industrial steel wool. Vc. 5—year ban on competing for the industrial steel wool customers formerly served by Williams "excepting that respondent may continue to sell industrial steel wool to any customer it served in common with Williams as of July, 1955, providing that the maximum unit annual quantity sold to each such common customer does not exceed the total unit quantity which respondent sold to it in the twelve months preceding July 5, 1955." 234 Special Comment Since industrial steel wool was the only area of competitive overlap between these two firms, Brillo being the only one of the two that produced household steel wool, Brillo was able to convince the FTC that the anticompetitive effects of the acquisition would be offset if it were to produce no industrial steel wool with the Williams assets. There are severe weaknesses in this order. Provision a almost precludes divestiture to anyone except those (few) firms which already had the manufacturing facilities to handle the Williams' business; i.e., the order in effect necessitates a horizontal divestiture to someone with excess steel wool production ready to take over the marketing function. Provision p, since theproduction facilities for steel wool are interchangeable between industrial and household steel wool, does in fact expand Brillo's capacity in industrial steel wool-—for Brillo, by using the Williams' assets to make household steel wool, will be able to free some of its equipment, formerly needed for household wool, for use in the production of industrial steel wool. And provision p, the marketing order, is clearly a protective device which "hallows" market shares until 1969 which existed in 1955. The Williams "business" was sold in January, 1965, to the J. H. Rhodes Co., of Chicago for $260,000. Ironically, as was mentioned in Chapter IV, Rhodes was unable to supply all the old Williams customers (under~ standable since Rhodes was unable to buy the Williams production facilities). The marketing order prevented the old Williams' customers from going to Brillo and Rhodes from sub—contracting his needs for industrial steel wool with Brillo. So, in 1965, the order was modified to allow Brillo to produce industrial steel wool in the Williams plant to supply Rhodes to in turn fill his customers orders. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 235 BROWN SHOE CO., INC.-G. R. KINNEY CO., INC. Complaint filed November 28, 1955; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1266. Disposed of by Final Judgment entered December 8, 1959, and affirmed by the Supreme Court. 1956 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,244-—Government motion for preliminary injunction denied and no commingling requirement instituted. 179 F. Supp. 721 (l959)——District Court finding of Section 7 violation. 370 U.S. 294 (l962)——Supreme Court affirmation of District Court. ' Date of merger: March, 1956, under conditions of no—commingling laid down by court. Relief Ordered. a. Full divestiture of Kinney. Special Comment Kinney was sold in August, 1963, to F. W. Woolworth for $39 million in cash and $6 million in promissory notes. Woolworth's size in retailing makes it a less- than-optimum purchaser, Woolworth being one of the 50 largest merchandising firms in the U.S. A case of SUFFICIENT relief. 236 CONTINENTAL BAKING-CO.—OMAR, INC. AND 7 OTHER BAKERY ACQUISITIONS Complaint filed May 5, 1960; Federal Trade Commission Docket 7880. Disposed of by Consent Order of May 11, 1962. 60 FTC 1183 (1952) Date of merger(s): 1952—1958; Omar, Inc.-—November, 1958. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 6 months of Omar, Inc. b. lO-year ban on acquisitions in bread and bread- type rolls without government approval. Special Comment The divestiture in this-case took place in November of 1963 with the 4 Omar plants being sold to a new entrant in the baking business headed by William Frostand known as OmarBakeries, Inc., purchase price was $4 million. But.thepartial divestiture negotiated in the consent order does not go far enough. Continental Baking was 'allowed to dispose of only one of the 8 acquisitions cited in the complaint—gandzat that, one with which it was-losing considerable-money even before the FTC complaint was-issued. It is quite likely thats Continental was glad to be rid of Omar! On the other hand, Continental was allowed to retain all of the. profitable bakeries. Of,8 acquisitions totaling over $25 million, it divested only 1, and the loser at that. A case of DEFICIENT relief. 237 CONTINENTAL CAN CO.-HAZEL-ATLAS GLASS CO. Complaint filed September 10, 1956; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1310. Disposed of by Opinion of Supreme Court, finding merger in violation of Section 7, June 22,1964. 1956 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68 ,479——Order denying government's motion for temporary restraining order. 217 F. Supp. 761 (l963)-—District Court dismissal of case. 378 U.S. 441 (l964)——Opinion of Supreme Court reversing. District Court. Date of merger: September, 1956. Relief‘Ordered Final Judgment on relief of November 18, 1964, called for: a. Divestiture of 9 of the 11 Hazel-Atlas plants. 1 b. lO—year ban on acquisitions in glass manufacture. Special~Comment Though structural relief was finally enacted in this, case, after the plants were held by Continental for 8 years, the divestiture ordered was not complete; 9 of the 11 plants were to be divested. Eight of these plants were sold in September of 1964 to Brockway Glass Company, already the 4th largest glass container producer in the U.S. (#2 as a result of the divestiture). Continental argued that since it lost so much money on Hazel-Atlas, it would be unwise to sell the assets to a firm not already in glass con— tainers since anyone else "would have no reasonable chance of succeeding." However, the validity of this assertion was never demonstrated. For essentially political reasons, Continental was. allowed to keep the two profitable plants in West Virginia (BNA ATRR 168: A-7 and Continental Annual Report, 1964, 45 The remaining plant to be divested was sold in 1963 to Alexander H. Kerr. 238 The relief is DEFICIENT, largely due to the inadequate buyer of the divested plants and also due to the partial divestiture. The Wall Street Journal quoted one antitrust lawyer as saying: Continental Can came out of it pretty well. It got rid of the HazeleAtlas plants it didn't-want, was allowed to keep the two better ones, and got a foothold in the glass business. (June 17, 1965, p. 12 239 CROWN ZELLERBACH-ST. HELENS PULP & PAPER CO. Complaint filed February 15, 1954; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6180. Disposed of by Supreme Court denial of petition for certiorari, June 25, 1962. 54 FTC 769 (1957)--Initial Decision of Hearing Examiner. and Order of divestiture. 54 FTC 798 (1957)-—Commission Opinion and Order of divestiture. 296 F. 2d 800 (1961—-affirming Commission's Opinion and Order of divestiture. 370 U. S. 937 (1962--certiorari petition denied by Supreme Court. Date of merger: June, 1953. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture "to restore St. Helens Pulp & Paper Company as a competitive entity in the paper trade, as organized and in substantially the basic operating form it existed at or around the time of the acquisition. Special Comment i This was the first litigated case which required the s divestiture of a large firm. In addition, the relief involved the question of considerablepost-acquisition improvements to the acquired property, Crown having put $14.3 million into St. Helens during litigation.‘ However the Commission wisely held that "the broad purpose of the statute cannot be thwarted merely because reSpondent has commingled its own assets with those of the acquired firm." (54 FTC at 807) Unfortunately, the relief in this case is DEFICIENT due to the Commission‘s approval of Boise Cascade Corporation as the buyer of the St. Helens facilities. Boise, by virtue of its timber holdings and lumber operations in the Pacific northwest, was a natural entrant into paper——in fact, it-had committed itself to pulp and paper as early as 1958 and gave every indication of entering the market on a large scale (see Annual Reports of Boise, 1957, p. 2, 1958, p. 2; 1959, p. 3). By 1963, a year before its acquisition ._. ._. . _, 240 of St. Helens, Boise's,Annua1 Report claimed: "Paper- is now our biggest business." (5} 1) Before buying St. Helens for $28 million in April, 1964, Boise Cascade had already made 5 acquisitions in paper and had constructed as many paper plants in the west. With the rapid expansion of the western paper market, 'it would not-seem unreasonable to expect a paper firm not already committed to this market to be the pur- chaser of St. Helens rather than one already in the market. There is evidence presented in Chapter IV Crown pursued only Boise as the buyer for these assets, ignoring other potential buyers. In addition, the terms of the sale so closely tie Crown and Boise together in reciprocal sales, pulp, and facilities agreements that one can justifiably question the degree of rivalry that will be found between the two companies (see "Agreement of Purchase and Sale," May 8, 1963). 241 DIAMOND CRYSTAL SALT CO.-JEFFERSON ISLAND SALT CO. Complaint filed December 2, 1958, Federal Trade Commission Docket 7323. Disposed of by Consent Order of February 4, 1960. 56 FTC 818 (1960). Date of merger: January, 1957. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of Jefferson's "Seneca Lake" property in New York. b. lO-year ban on acquisitions in salt production or salt distribution. 0. lO-year marketing order requiring Diamond to offer to sell up to 30% of the annual production of rock salt at Jefferson, La. "in good faith in accordance-with respondent's regular credit requirements, and at respondent's regular prices, terms, and. conditions, and in weights and packages, types and grades, regularly produced at respondent's Jefferson Island plant, to all other producers of salt who do not have resources and facilities for the production of Louisiana Rock Salt ." This is further complicated by a system of allotments to purchasers based on their past purchases. Special Comment This case is an example of de minimus divestiture, the "Seneca Lake" property commanding a price of $4,000 in June, 1960, from a resident of the area, Robert Hillman of Rock Stream, New York. The marketing order is a complex one, attempting to "protect" the non—O integrated users of Louisiana Rock Salt while letting the heart of the acquisition go unsevered. The relief is Clearly UNSUCCESSFUL. 242 DIEBOLD INC.-—HERRING-HALL-MARVIN SAFE CO. Complaint filed August 24, 1959; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1471. DiSposed of by Consent Decree of May 10, 1963. 197 F. Supp. 902 (l961)--DistrictCourt summary dis- missal of complaint. 369 U.S. 654 (l962)--Supreme Court reversal of District Court and remand for trial on the merits. 1963.CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,738--Consent Decree. Date of merger: September, 1959. Relief»Ordered a. Divestiture within one year of Herring-Hall—Marvin, reactivating it as "an operating business." b. Divestiture order dropped-if, after 1% years, compliance has been unsuccessful.. c. 5-year ban on acquisitions in the production or distribution of bank protection equipment, without government approval; increasing to 10 years if there is no divestiture ofHerring-Hall-Marvin. Special Comment Diebold never complied with the divestiture order and was allowed to keep Herring-Hall—Marvin. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 243 FARM JOURNAL, INC.-CURTIS PUBLISHING CO. (COUNTRY GENTLEMAN) Complaint filed June 30, 1955; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6388. Disposed of by Order of Commission adopting Initial Decision of Hearing Examiner, July 17, 1956. 53 FTC 26 (1956). Date of merger: September, 1955. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of trade names, subscriber lists, and advertiser lists of Country Gentleman magazine. Special Comment This case involved the acquisition by the nation's largest general interest farm magazine of its only national competitor. Since Farm Journal had already solicited the subscribers of Country-Gentleman, transferring their subscriptions, and already had the use of the advertising lists, this divestiture was able to accomplish little. Restoring Country Gentleman was, for practical purposes, impossible. The ”Country Gentleman" name was sold for $1 to Patent Press, Inc., in December, 1956; the same month the other trade name involved, "Better Farming," was sold to Watt Publishing Co. for $500. The two lists brought $30,000 from Mailing Service Inc. in November, 1956. Relief in this case is UNSUCCESSFUL. 244 GAMBLE—SKOGMO, INC.-WESTERN AUTO SUPPLY CO. Complaint filed April 1, 1960; Antitrust Division. Blue Book No. 1513. Disposed of by Consent Decree of July 18, 1960. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,770. Date of merger: sufficient capital stock for control acquired-by August, 1958. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of stock had taken place by the time of the consent decree; the decree prohibited~ Gamble-Skogmo or its president from acquiring any future interest in Western Auto and the exchange of information between Gamble-Skogmo and Western Auto. Special Comment Though the consent order did not call for divestiture, the effect of the Section 7 action was the stock divestitureIMIUflioccurred Just prior to the consent decree. The stock was soldin July, 1960, to Beneficial Finance Co. for $45.2 million. Those who are unconcerned about conglomerate or "long—pocket" acquisitions might consider the relief in this case as successful. However I evaluated it as SUFFICIENT. While structural relief was enacted, and rather quickly Beneficial Finance would not seem to be the most ideal of purchasers due to its size and "long-pocket." This case is a borderlineone, the deciding factor being one's views on acquisitions by large conglomerates. I rate it SUFFICIENT, with the reminder that this category represents satisfac— tory relief settlements. 245 GENERAL SHOE CORP. (NOW GENESCO)-DELMAN, INC. AND 17 OTHER ACQUISITIONS Complaint filed March 29, 1955; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1220. Disposed of by Consent Decree of February 17, 1956. 1956 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,271. Date of merger(s): 1950—1954, with 18 acquisitions mentioned in complaint; Delman, Inc. purchased in January, 1955. Relief Ordered a. 5-year ban on acquisitions in shoe industry without government approval. b. Divestiture within 2 years of stock in each shoe manufacturer or shoe retailer in which a minority of outstanding stock is held. c. 5-year requirement to purchase a minimum of 20% of its shoes from other shoe manufacturers. d. Provision for patent licensing at reasonable royalties and the supply of technical assistance to other shoe manufacturers. Special Comment Structural relief was substituted in this decree for a ban on future acquisitions, patent licensing, and the regulation of Genesco's purchases of its shoe require— ments. No significant structural relief was ordered. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 246 GULF OIL CORP.-WARREN PETROLEUM CORP. Complaint filed December 13, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6689. Disposed of by Consent Order of January 5, 1960. 56 FTC 688 (1960). Date of merger: March, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 3 years of certain Warren properties to buyers other than 23 specified oil companies: the "Harris properties": Butane Gas, Inc., Butane Wholesale Gas Co., Harris Distributors, Inc. Dri—Gas division . all railroad tank cars owned or controlled by Warren natural gas facilities at San Pedro, Cal. petrochemical plant at Conroe, Texas Madill gas processing plant, Madill, Okla. Ringwood gas processing plant, Ringwood, Okla. Midland gas processing plant, Conroe, Texas. b. lO—year ban on acquiring more than 20% of the assets of any producer of LP or natural gas marketer with U.S. sales of more than 125 million gallons of LP and/or natural gas. 0. lO—year requirement to offer 48.64% of their LP gas to independent, non—integrated LP gas marketers. d. lO—year requirement to offer 2.58% of their LP gas to independent, non-major refiners. e. lO—year requirement to offer 44.8% of their natural gasoline to independent U.S. non—major refiners. f. lO—year requirement to offer 3.52% of their total supply of LP gas to independent non—integrated U.S. petrochemical manufacturers. 247 Special Comment This order is UNSUCCESSFUL due to both the marketing order, which is extremely complex, and to the insuf- ficiency of the divestiture requirement. The whole order runs 10 pages with the marketing percentages being established to the second decimal point. The marketing order requires only that Gulf "offer" these percentages for sale to certain non—majors--which brings in the question of "intent" in ascertaining whether the "offers" have been in good faith when the percentage requirements are not met. The greatest problem with the marketing order was outlined in Chapter IV——namely that markets change, and Gulf found, in some cases, that there simply was no market for the percentages it was required to offer. The complexities in administering this marketing order, and the misallocative results that would follow were it closely adhered to for ten years, clearly point out that the marketing order is a euphemism for government regulation. The assets to be divested in this case were parceled out in a piecemeal fashion to 10 different purchasers, with 29% of the acquired assets being divested and less than 4% ending up in the hands of small independents in the petroleum industry. No part of the order resulted in another independent center of initiative being added to the petroleum industry to replace Warren. The acquisition gave Gulf its foothold in natural gas and certain key personnel from Warren, including the services of W. K. Warren who now sits on Gulf’s board. This has manifested itself in Gulf's above—average industry discovery rate for natural gas (Annual Re orts, Gulf Oil Corporation, 1962, p. 7; 1965, p. 8). The divested assets went to: Harris properties, Dri-Gas division to Thermo-Gas Co. in August, 1962, for $10.1 million; since acquired by Mid—America Pipeline Co. railroad tank cars—-sold piecemeal with bulk of them- going to General American Transportation in July, 1962, for $19 million, the largest lessor of tank cars in the U.S. San Pedro natural gas facilities-—to Bray Oil, Calif., in December, 1964, for $450,000 Conroe petrochemical plant—-Jefferson Chemical Corp., a subsidiary of Texaco, in January, 1960, for $500,000 248 Madill & Ringwood plants—-to National Fuels Corp., Texas in December, 1962 for $4,860,000. Midland p1ant-—to Champlin Oil & Refining Co. in December, 1962 for $3,530,000; now owned by Celanese Corp. oxygen equipment at Conroe p1ant——to Grenader Equipment in December, 1960 for $62,500; now owned by Jefferson Chemical. The relief in this case is UNSUCCESSFUL. 249 THE HERTZ CORP.—37 MOTOR VEHICLE RENTING AND LEASING COMPANIES Complaint filed May 1, 1959; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1444. Disposed of by Consent Decree of June 29, 1960. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,762. Date of merger(s): 1954—1958. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of one Miami Beach car rental agency and one New York City truck rental agency. b. 5-year ban on non-competition covenants in car and truck rental business and on exclusive concessions agreements without government approval. 0. 3—year ban on acquisitions in motor vehicle rental business in those cities where Hertz already has 50 plus cars and/or trucks, without government approval. Special Comment This is an example of de minimus divestiture with some marketing orders thrown in for good measure. The value of the assets mentioned in the complaint totalled $40 million. The Miami Beach business was sold in March of 1961 as a market extension acquisition to American Material and Equipment Company, car renters in New Orleans, for less than $500,000. The truck rental business in New York was Sold for less than $3 million in April, 1962, to Tetrick Leasing Corporation which subsequently went broke, the operation reverting back to Hertz. Altogether, 162 cars in Miami were sold. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 250 HILTON HOTELS CORP.-HOTELS STATLER CO. (control of 9 "first~class" hotels and l in construction) Complaint filed April 27, 1955; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1229. Disposed of by Consent Decree of February 6, 1956. 1956 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,253. Date of merger: October, 1954. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of 3 hotels, the Jefferson in St. Louis, the Mayflower in Washington, D.C., and' either the Roosevelt or the New Yorker in New York City. b. 5-year ban on hotel acquisitions in selected cities without government approval. Special Comment Hilton, the largest hotel chain in the U.S. by value 'of assets, revenues, and number of rooms, acquired Statler, the second largest hotel chain in the U.S.. The relief ordered did not require divestiture of any of the hotels acquired in the acquisition; instead Hilton was allowed to substitute 3 of its own hotels in-compliance with the order. The consent decree is lacking in 3 ways: a. it is a partial divestiture, 3 hotels being sold where 9 were gained b. there is evidence that the substitution of hotels was indeed to Hilton's advantage: the occupancy rate of the hotels kept was 5% greater than those divested; the average number of rooms per hotel kept was-1,033, of those divested, 888. The order resulted in Hilton keeping Statler hotels in Boston, Buffalo, Cleveland, Dallas} Detroit, Hartford, Los Angeles, New York, St. Louis, and Washington D.C. (see Moody's 1956 Bank & Finance Manual, ’ pp. 786-790) *Opened in January, 1956- 251 c. the 3 hotels which were sold went to less than could be desired purchasers: the Jefferson was sold in December, 1955, for $7.5 million to the Sheraton Corporation of America; the Mayflower. and the Roosevelt were sold in March, 1956, for $14.9 million to the Hotel Corporation of America. The relief obtained is UNSUCCESSFUL. 252 HOOKER CHEMICAL CORP.-DUREZ PLASTICS & CHEMICALS, INC.- and the molding materials assets of- Monsanto Chemical Co. Complaint filed July 28, 1960; Federal Trade Commission Docket 8034. Disposed of by Consent Order of August 31, 1961. 59 FTC 254 (1961). Date of merger(s): February, 1955, and September, 1958, respectively. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 90 days of the assets acquired; from Monsanto Chemical Co. b. lO-year ban on acquisitions of manufacturers or~ distributors of phenolic molding compounds. c. 6-month requirement to make available to the purchaser at-Hooker's cost its requirements of lump resins and resin compounds-needed to manu- facture phenolic molding compounds; to make available technical assistance; and to make available customer lists of those firms pur—. chasing phenolic molding compounds. Special Comment Relief is UNSUCCESSFUL in this case due to the partial divestiture and the failure of the decree to re-establish -even one viable firm. The combined purchase price of the two firms mentioned in the complaint is over $63, million. The assets to be divested brought$150,000, from the Duraphane Co. of Sterling, Conn.- The assets were never used and are now in the hands of Union Carbide. 253 INTERNATIONAL PAPER CO.—LONG BELL LUMBER CORP. Complaint filed November 6, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6676 Disposed of by Consent Order of June 25, 1957. 53 FTC 1192 (1957) Date of merger: November, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 10 years of stock in Longview Fibre Co., held by Long Bell prior to its being acquired. b. 10—year ban on acquisitions in paper or paperboard production or the converting thereof if such facil— ities compete with any International Paper Co. mill. c. lO—year marketing order regarding International's proposed mill in the Pacific coast area directing it to contract to sell 40 per.cent of its tonnage of paperboard to nonintegrated purchasers in an. ll—state area. Special Comment Long—Bell had planned to build a kraft pulp and paper mill in the Pacific northwest. This merger, and the. following failure on the part of-the government to secure divestiture, foreclosed Long—Bell's entry into the paper industry on the west coast. The stock in. Longview Fibre was sold by 1963 at an estimated price» of $13.6 million, Long—Bell costing International Paper $117 million in 1956. The attempt to ”protect" the non—integrated converters by a marketing order in; lieu of divestiture makes this-relief UNSUCCESSFUL. 254 JERROLD ELECTRONICS CORP.-IO COMMUNITY ANTENNA SYSTEMS . Complaint filed February 15, 1957, amended to include- a Section 7 violation on April 2,1959; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1318. Disposed of by Final Judgment of District Court, chober 11, 1960; affirmed»by Supreme Court, March-20, l9 1 ' ‘ 187 F. Supp. 545 (l960)--opinion of District Court. 365 U. S. 567 (l96l)--per curiam affirmation of judgment by Supreme Court. Date of merger(s): 1955-1959° Relief'Ordered a. Ban on=future_acquisitions of community television antenna systems until April 2, 1962. b. Marketing orders: - no tyingin of equipment sales with services: - no tying-of service sales with equipment - no tying in of equipment sales with other equipment - no covenants not to purchase from Jerrold rivals_ to be entered with customers, subject to certain provisions. Special Comment *This is an eXample of the substitution of a marketing order and a future ban on acquisitions for structural relief. All ten acquisitions were allowed to stand. By structural standards, this relief is UNSUCCESSFUL. , 255 LESLIE SALT CO.-DESERET SALT CO. & CALIFORNIA-SALT CO. Complaint filed December 14, 1960; Federal Trade- Commission,DocketK8220. Disposed of by Consent Order of December 8, 196l.> 59 FTC 1278 (1961) Date of.merger(s): December, 1958, and January, 1958, respectively. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture-of Deseret Salt Co. b. lO—year ban on acquiring any U.S. salt producer or distributor. c. At buyeris option, it may sell Leslie up to 25,000 tons of salt per year for 2 years, with priCe determined by an FTC formula. Special Comment The California Salt Co. acquisition was not considered as,a,partcxfthe relief problem in this analysis since- .the acquisition was actually made in 1924 with Leslie owning two-thirds of California‘s.stock since 1936. The complaint with regard to California Salt wash dismissed. The Deseret.facilities were divested in November, 1965, to the Hardy Salt Co. of St. Louis for $631,000. Hardy then becamea new entry in this region- makingthe relief in this case SUFFICIENT. 256 LUCKY LAGER BREWING CO.-FISHER BREWING CO. Complaint filed February 18, 1958; Antitrust Division Blue Book N00 1370. Disposed of by Consent Decree of October 6, 1958. 1958 CCH Trade Cases, Par.-69,160. 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,508 (denial of plea to modify consent decree). Date of merger: June, 1957. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of Fisher Brewing Company within 9;months. b. If no divestiture. takes place within 9 months, then Lucky Lager may keep Fisher but the two would be "perpetually enjoined and restrained .-- . from selling . . . more than 39% of the beer consumed in Utah." c. Banon brewery acquisitions in Utah. d.* 5-year ban on acquisitions in brewing without government approval. Special Comment No divestiture was made during the 9 months allotted for the sale; therefore Lucky Lager retained possession of Fisher with the 39% market share rule going into effect--this being the share of the market Fisher had at the time of its acquisition by Lucky Lager. This is an example of the government, by injunction, trying to. preserve a past market share. Since Lucky Lager had about 12% of the Utah beer market prior to its acqui—; sition of.Fisher, this marketing Order forced the respondent intoselling less beer than it had been. selling in Utah. Not surprisingly, Lucky Lager found it could not afford to sell beer in Utah under-this“ market share restriction. Though Lucky' 8 original attempt to have the order modified was rejected, I learned from the Antitrust Division that the 39% require- ment was quietly drOpped when its results became apparent. With no structural relief and an unfortunate attempt at market share control by the government, this relief is UNSUCCESSFUL. 257 MAREMONT AUTOMOTIVE.PRODUCTS, INC.— SACO-LOWELL.SHOPS Complaint_origina11y filed June 23,1960, amended December 9, 1960; Antitrust Division Blue Book No.-1543. -Disposed.of by Consent Decreeof December 9, 1960. 1960 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 69,881. Date of merger: May, 1960 (23%); October, 1961 (91%). Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of Saco-Lowell muffler manufacturing. facilities. b. Maremont barred from purchasing or distributing ,mufflers made in these facilities or from dis- criminating in sales to any purchasers.of. mufflers made by Saco—Lowell facilities. c._ 3eyear ban on-acquisitions of any muffler manu- facturing firm. Special Comment Though divestiture was ordered, Maremont claimed that after 2-years of attempting to comply with the order, it hadabeengunsuccessful. The District Court, in, January of 1963, rescinded the divestiture order. The relief is UNSUCCESSFUL. . :' 258 MINNESOTA MINING & MANUFACTURING CO.— PREHLER ELECTRICAL INSULATION CO. & INSULATION & WIRES INC., A SUBSIDIARY OF i ESSEX WIRE CORP. ‘ l l Complaint filed June 24, 1960; Federal Trade Commission Docket 7973. Disposed of by Consent Order of August 24, 1961. 59 FTC 321 (1961). Date of merger(s): March, 1956, and August, 1956, respectively. Relief-Ordered a. Divestiture of Insulation & Wires Inc. before January 1, 1962. b. lO-year ban on acquisitions of any distributors of electrical insulation products. c. 5—year requirement to make available to the purchaser of Insulation & Wires the electrical insulation products manufactured by MMM on the, same terms as these products are sold to other distributors. d. 5—year requirement that Prehler, which continues under MMM ownership, buys 22% of its total annual purchases of electrical insulation products from- suppliers other than MMM. Special Comment In my analysis, relief is considered Deficient when structural relief borders on Sufficient but a complex marketing order is added to the decree. In this case the structural relief is only partia1—-and by itself would make the case a toss—up between the Deficient and the Sufficient categories. However the marketing order definitely drops the case to the lower rung. This marketing order was not an easy one for the government to enforce, with considerable question later arising as to what products constituted those falling within the 22% purchase requirement. 259 The divestiture part of the consent order was completed, in October, 1961, when-Insulation & Wires was repur— chased by its former parent, Essex Wire Corp. However. Prehler, the larger of the two acquisitions and the second largest distributor of electrical insulation products in the U.S.,-remained with MMM. In light of MMMlslpast.acquisition;history in electrical .insulation.(8 acquisitions from 1952-1956) and its dominant position in electrical insulation tapes, Prehler should also have been divested, leaving MMM as a potential competitor to both the new Prehler and Insulation & Wires. A case of DEFICIENT relief. 260 NATIONAL DAIRY PRODUCTS CO.—21 CORPORATE AND 18 NON—CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS IN THE DAIRY INDUSTRY AND 1 ACQUISITION IN THE VEGETABLE OIL INDUSTRY Complaint filed October 16, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6651. Disposed of by Consent Order of January 30, 1963. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder' 1961—1963), Par. 16,282. Date of merger(s): 1951—1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 18 months of two dairy acquisitions: White Ice Cream and Milk Company, Wilmington, N. C., and Plains Creamery, Inc., Amarillo, Texas, with National barred from com— peting in these markets in the sale-of processed fluid milk for 5 years. b.' Ban on future acquisitions without government: approval until October, 1963. Special Comment Divestiture of the White assets took place in June of 1964,125 months after the acquisition, to E. H. Evans and a number of local investors for $1.3 million; now operating as Whitebrook Farms Inc. Divestiture of the Plains assets took place in January of 1965, 124 months after the acquisition, to L. B. Parker of Dallas, a former manager for the Borden Co., and A. C. Goldtrap, owner of the Ace Milk Co. of Fort Smith, Ark., for $1.46 million; presently operating under the same name, Plains Creamery. This is a difficult case to evaluate. Since the acquisitions in the complaint were acquired by National] Dairy for $14.28 million, a divestiture of less than $3 million may seem to be of de minimus proportions and a case of Unsuccessful relief. Actually I have class- ified this case as DEFICIENT. Though the structural relief which took place is only partial, two of the most important acquisitions were severed. In addition, 261 though there are 39 acquisitions in the complaint, in some of the cases these were not processors of fluid; milk products but rather milk routes or creamery stations of a rather small size, presenting no great anticompetitive problems. In this antimerger action, as was the case with the Foremost example given in Chapter IV of the text, there were facilities closed down or converted shortly after their being acquired. Though structural relief would have been difficult if not impossible in some of these cases, it is unfortunate that the following acquisitions were allowed to stand. a. Versailles Farm Products Co., St. Louis, Mo.-- a modern, profitable operation and an important producer of ungraded milk for National-Dairy's Kraft Foods Co. b.' Ak-SareBen Ice Cream Co. and Irvington Dairy, both of Irvington, Neb.——both profitable oper- ations competing with a National Dairy subsidiary. 0. Garden Farm Dairy Inc., Denver, Colo.--a large~ and profitable milk and milk products company, the third largest in the Denver area. d. Giles County Dairy Products, Pulaski, Tenn.—— primarily a cheese producer in competition with National Dairy's Kraft Foods Co. e. Indiana Condensed Milk, Indianapolis, Ind.—- though ICM was liquidating its assets, National was an unfortunate purchaser-in view of its position in this market. The operation-was converted from condensed milk to cheese and, by 1962, completely absorbed in National's. operations in the Indiana area. f. Ballard Ice Cream Co., Indianapolis, Ind.—— a company directly competing with a National subsidiary, closed down after 6 months-and consolidated with National's Huntingdon plant. g. United Dairy Farms of Albany, Inc., Albany, N. Y.-- a profitable firm in competition with a National' subsidiary, since converted from milk processing to cottage cheese production. 262 The largest acquisition in the group, the Humko Co., was purchased for over $8 million; National wastumko's largest customer-for Humko's edible oils, used mainly: in salad dressings and mayonnaiseetype dressings produced by National Dairy's Kraft Foods Co. There was no relief-taken concerning this acquisition. 263 NATIONAL SUGAR REFINING CO.—CERTAIN-ASSETS ACQUIRED FROM GODCHAUX SUGARS, INC. Complaint filed July 25, 1957; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6852. Disposed of by Consent Order of February 1, 1962. 60 FTC Ell (1962). Date of merger: June, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture within 6 months of the assets acquired from Godchaux. b. S—year ban on acquisitions in sugar refining and beet processing. Special Comment Divestiture took place in the "spring of 1962” (May?) for $9.7 million. The divested assets are now-owned by a new company, Godchaux Sugar Refining Co., a new entrant into the business headed by the "new" Godchaux's president, J. Lobo. A case of SUCCESSFUL relief. 264 OWENS—ILLINOIS GLASS CO.— NATIONAL CONTAINER CORP. Complaint filed December 4, 1956; Antitrust_Division- Blue Book No. 1310. Disposed of by Consent Decree of July 8, 1963. 1963 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,808. Date of merger: October, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of properties acquired from National Container to include: — the Jacksonville, Fla., paperboard mill, - 5 fiber box manufacturing plants — inventories of the above properties — at the purchaser's option, 209,000 acres of woodland as a source of pulpwood. b° If the woodland option is taken, purchaser must agree to sell pulpwood to certain Owens—Illinois plants; if not taken, Owens-Illinois must agree' to meet certain pulpwood needs of the purchaser. for up to 10 years. Special Comment Relief in this case can be characterized as "too little and too late." According to the 1956 Moody's Industrials (p. 884), National Container was comprised ofv7 paper mills, l8 converting plants, and 514,000 acres of timber. The divestiture called for the sale of only 1 of 7 paper mills and but 5 of the 18 converting plants, leaving Owens with the bulk of the acquisition. The property to be divested was sold in April, 1965, to the Alton Box Board Company, Alton, Illinois, for an undisclosed sum. Thus, even the plants Owens finally had to sell were held for more than 8 years. The divested plants did go to a satisfactory buyer, Alton being one of the smaller container companies, as a market and product extension acquisition enabling Alton to expand its operation in the southwest and southeast. The partial divestiture is the "hole" in this case, a case of DEFICIENT relief. 265 REYNOLDS METALS CO.—ARROW BRANDS, INC. Complaint filed December 27, 1957; Federal Trade Commission Docket 7009. Disposed of by Circuit Court affirmation of Commission Order to divest. 56 FTC 743 (l960)——Commission Opinion and_0rder to Divest. 309 F. 2d 223 (l962)——Commission Order affirmed. Date of merger: August, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of Arrow ”as a competitive entity." The Circuit Court modified the divestiture order in that Reynolds was not required to divest the building it had purchased, after the acquisition, to house Arrow Brands. (Arrow, prior to its being acquired, operated in a leased building.) Special Comment No divestiture resulted in this case, Reynolds finding it impossible to sell the Arrow equipment without a building. The court claimed ”after-acquired properties are not relevant” but, in fact, they are in the securing of structural relief. No doubt Arrow would have made a more attractive package if the building were included in the divestiture order. The order to divest was modified on May 26, 1966, since Reynolds was unable to find a buyer. The quid pro quo for the dropping of the divestiture order makes little sense--in return for drOpping the divestiture order, Reynolds is required to withdraw from the foil business and refrain from having any interest in any florist foil or laminated aluminum gift wrap company for 5 years. According to Reynolds, this modification of the order would "accomplish the ends the Commission has in mind and-would enhance the competi- tive situation the Commission is desirous of maintaining, in the florist foil industry." (letter from Reynolds to FTC of Dec. 27, 1965). By what process this modification enhances competition in florist foil is beyond my ken. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 266 RYDER SYSTEM, INC.—l7 TRUCK RENTAL FIRMS Complaint filed October 3, 1960; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 15 . Disposed of by Consent Judgment of June 15, 1961. 1961 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,056. 1962 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 70,443 (modification ofi order reducing divestiture requirement). Date of merger(s): May, 1955—November, 1959. Relief.Ordered a. Divestiture of 100 trucks in Atlanta and Chicago; 75 trucks in Dallas and Nashville; 50 trucks in Memphis. b. 3—year ban on acquiring any truck leasing oper— ation in any of 65 cities where Ryder had 50 or more trucks, without government approval. Special Comment The 17 acquisitions mentioned in the complaint were acquired by Ryder at a cost of $20 million and included approximately 8700 trucks. The divestiture of 400 trucks is a partial divestiture of de minimus propor— tions. Ryder parceled the trucks out in a rather piece— meal fashion and without great haste. After one year, by June, 1962, the Atlanta and Dallas requirement had been met but only 60 trucks had been sold in Chicago, 7 in Nashville, and none in Memphis. In August of 1962, the order was modified to accept the 60 sold in Chicago as meeting the requirement, droppin the total to be sold to 360 trucks. Then in July, 1963, after Ryder had sold 44 of the 50 required in Memphis, the order was considered to be met. Thus Ryder finally sold 354 trucks. A partial divestiture of this nature is UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 267 SCHENLEY INDUSTRIES, INC.—PARK & TILFORD DISTILLERS CORP. Complaint filed February 14, 1955; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1214. Disposed of by Consent Decree of April 3, 1957. 1957 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 68,664. Date of merger: December, 1954. Relief Ordered a. 10—year ban on acquiring any other whisky distiller or whisky distributor without government approval.» Special Comment Only a ban on future acquisitions resulted from this i case—~the government not pressing a demand for divest- iture "on the theory that nobody would want to buy Park & Tilford." (WSJ, April 4, 1957, p. 4) In the_ time span from the EEEuisition to the consent decree, many foreign suppliers of whisky, who distributed; through Park & Tilford, had canceled their agency requirements with Park & Tilford; consequently the company became, under Schenley’s parentage, a shell. The lack of any structural relief makes this-case' UNSUCCESSFUL. 268 SCOTT PAPER CO.—SOUNDVIEW PULP CO. DETROIT SULPHITE PULP & PAPER CO. HOLLINGSWORTH & WHITNEY CO. Complaint filed June 1, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6559. Disposed of by Consent Order of April 23, 1964. 57 FTC 1415 (l960)——Commission Opinion and Order of- divestiture. 301 F. 2d 579 (l962)--Opinion and Order remanding case to FTC for taking of additional evidence. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder» 1963—1965), Par. 16,706—-Opinion of the Commission on Remand reaffirming Section 7 violation. 1964 CCH Trade Cases, Par. 71, O97-—Consent Order. Date of merger(s): November, 1951, September, 1954, and October, 1954 respectively. Relief Ordered a. Ban on acquisitions of any firms engaged in the manufacture or distribution of sanitary paper products without FTC approval. b. If Scott acquires any concern not manufacturing sanitary paper products within 10 years, Scott is not to rebuild any of the paper machines acquired to sanitary paper products production for 10 years, or, if Scott acquires a pulp mill, it is I not to use any of the pulp in the manufacture of sanitary paper products. c. Scott is to attempt to divest 2 rebuilt paper- machines at the Detroit operation after 5 years; these are to be sold by the end of 7 years to an FTC-approved purchaser who will use the machines for sanitary paper products production. If, at the end of 7 years, this divestiture has not taken.place, Scott is barred from using any paper machine acquired in the Detroit operation in the production of sanitary paper products. 269 Special Comment The Commission was bold in its initial order to divest, calling for the divestiture of all 3 firms including improvements, since all 3 violated Section 7. This would have been a sizable divestiture since the purchase- price of the 3 firms totaled over $100 million and Scott had put an additional $109 million in capital additions and improvements into the facilities. But in its modification of the order, the Commission did an almost complete reversal. Structural relief is now limited to 2 paper machines, to take place 17 years after they were acquired! The rest of the order consists of an artificial attempt to keep Scott from; becoming too dominant in sanitary paper products. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 270 SCOVILL MFG. CO.—DELONG HOOK & EYE CO. Complaint filed March 12, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6527. Disposed of by Consent Order of September 15, 1956. 53 FTC 260 (1956) Date of merger: April, 1955. ReliefrOrdered a. Divestiture within 90 days of all machines and related equipment at DeLong plant used in the manufacture of safety and common pins. b. Ban on manufacturing safety and common-pins in DeLong factory. Special Comment This case provides an-example of partial divestiture, Scovill successfully convincing the Commission that- since the only area of competitive overlap involved in the acquisition was the manufacture of safety and common pins, satisfactory relief would require only to sell these pin machines and refrain from using the acquired plant to make these pins. An order of this sort almost dictates divestiture to an established pin manufacturer, which is what happened, the machinery going to the Star Pin Co. of Shelton, Conn., for $47,116 in December, 1956. The divest- iture was de minimus, DeLong being purchased for $1.8 million. No independent pin manufacturer was restored. Horizontal divestiture, and de minimus divestiture at that, is UNSUCCESSFUL. 271 SIMPSON TIMBER CO.-M&M WOODWORKING CO. Complaint filed January 4, 1960; Federal Trade Commission Docket 7713. Disposed of by Consent Order of January 4, 1962. 60 FTC 43 (1962). Date of merger: August, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of 500,000,000 board feet of redwood timber over a l3-year period at a rate not less than 35,000,000 board feet/ year and at a price less than $20 per 1,000 board feet for stumpage plus 8%/year compounded from 1/1/61 to cover carrying costs. Five companies are excluded as purchasers. b. Ban on acquiring over 100,000,000 board feet of old growth redwood, in the form of either timberlands or logs. c. lO—year ban on acquiring any redwood sawmills. d. Ban on owning more than 202,000 acres of. redwood-type timberlands during duration of this order. Special Comment In this case, a marketing order was substituted for structural relief. The order does nothing to re- establish another independent grower and seller of redwood timber. Ironically, the order accomplishes nothing which Simpson would not have done itself as~ the owner of M&M. Simpson exceeded its 35 million board ft/yr. requirement indicating that sales of this magnitude were what it would normally consum— mate, sans the marketing order. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. 272 A. G. SPALDING & BROS.—RAWLINGS MFG. CO. Complaint filed December 8, 1955; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6478. Disposed of by Circuit Court affirmation of Commission Order to divest, March 22, 1962. 56 FTC 1155 (l960)—-Commission's Opinion and Order to divest. 301 F. 2d 585 (l962)——affirming Commission. Date of merger: December, 1955. Relief Ordered i a. Divestiture of Rawlings' assets so as to restore Rawlings as a viable competitor. Special Comment Divestiture took place in October of 1963 for $10 million to a group of private investors headed by John L. Burns, former president of ‘ RCA. The group had no previous connection with the manufacture or distribution of sporting goods. A case of SUCCESSFUL relief. 273 STANDARD OIL CO. OF OHIO- LEONARD REFINERIES, INC. Complaint filed December 31, 1959; Antitrust Division Blue Book No. 1490. Disposed of, without prejudice, January 22, 1960, pursuant to a stipulation based on defendant's, non-merger agreement of January 20, 1960. Date of merger: never consummated. Relief Ordered a. No relief necessary due to defendants' agreement not to merge. Special Comment This case is included in the sample since it was a government Section 7 action that stopped this merger, even though no "official" Section 7 victory accrued to the government. Since the. merger was stopped in its incipiency, this case falls in the SUCCESSFUL category. 274 UNION BAG & PAPER CORP.-HANKINS CO. Complaint filed June 30, 1955; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6391. Disposed of by Consent Order of March 23, 1956. 52 FTC 1278-(1956). Date of merger: June-July, 1954, 8 1/3% of Hankins stock purchased. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of any Hankins stock held by Union Bag & Paper.over 9%‘of.thatv outstanding. b. Removal of any interlocking directorates between the two firms. Special Comment In this case, Union was attempting to take over control of Hankins-by purchase of stock and the placing of men on the Hankins' board. The relief nipped any potential restraint in the bud by- removing any interlocking directorates and, limiting Union's stock ownership in Hankins. Acaseof SUCCESSFUL relief. 275 UNION CARBIDE CORP.—VISKING CORP. Complaint filed July 8, 1957; Federal Trade Commission Docket 6826. Disposed of by Commission approval of sale of assets, November 1, 1963. 59 FTC 614 (l96l)——Commission Opinion and Order to divest. CCH Trade Regulation Reporter (FTC Transfer Binder 196311965), Par. 16,638—-Commission order approving sale of assets. Date of merger: December, 1956. Relief Ordered a. Divestiture of Visking's polyethylene film manufacturing facilities, with the exception of the new film plant in Cartersville, Ga. Special Comment The Visking operation at the time of acquisition consisted of 3 plants producing polyethylene film; in addition, Visking did about 50% of its business in cellulose meat casings. Union Carbide kept the latter operation as well as a new film plant that was built by Visking after it was acquired. Consequently this is a case of partial divestiture, Visking costing Union $91 million and being divested; for $17 million. The divestiture took place in November, 1963, to the Ethyl Corp. The combination of a partial divestiture and the rather poor selec— tion of a buyer makes for a case of DEFICIENT relief. While Ethyl is not the worst of all purchasers of_ the assets, potential competition was lost in the sale. As Ethyl's 1963 Annual Report puts it: the acquisition "strengthens our position in the packaging field, where the film is widely used, and fits very well into our situation as a producer of paper and packaging materials and a manufacturer. of chemical intermediaries for other plastics." (p. 4). Though Ethyl is a better buyer of these 276 assets than the others Union suggested, such as Allied Chemical, Texaco, Socony—Vacuum, and Celanese, I lean with the dissents of Commis- sioners Elman and Higginbotham that a better purchaser should have been found. At any rate, as a memorandum from the FTC's Bureau of Economics put it, Ethyl is a "minimally acceptable" pur- chaser (Memo of 10/7/63). The Cartersville plant, which was not divested, was in every way a part of the Visking organization—-it was constructed and operated by Visking people and its products were marketed through the Visking division. By keeping this plant, Union Carbide retained sig- nificant fruits of the acquisition. 277 THE VENDO CO.-VENDORLATOR MANUFACTURING CO. Complaint filed October 11, 1956; Federal Trade Commission Docket 664 . Disposed of by Consent Order of September 5, 1957. 54 FTC 253 (1957). Date of merger: September, 1956. Relievardered ' a. Divestiture of trademarks and patents acquired. in the merger. b. lO—year ban on acquisitions of soft drink dispenser manufacturers. ; Special Comment No meaningful structural relief took place in this case. The patents and trademarks to be divested were apparently quite worthless; no one even tried to purchase them. A case of UNSUCCESSFUL relief. APPENDIX B 278 (a) (b) (C) (d) AGGREGATE COMPLAINT AND DIVESTITURE VALUES FROM CHAPTER III The total value of assets against which 19 of the 21' FTC Section_7 complaints were issued is $665,927,000. This sum represents the market price of all acqui— sitions included in the sample cases with the following exceptions: Minnesota Mining & Manufacturing; Union Bag & Paper Co. Most of these figures are taken from the Commission complaints, corporate records, or the business press. A promise of confidentiality on. some of the prices comprising this total prevents a case-by-case breakdown of these figures. The total value of assets against which 13 of the 18 Department of Justice Section 7 complaints were issued is $466,028,000. This sum represents the market price of all acquisitions included in the sample cases with the following exceptions: American Cyanamid; Bethlehem Steel; General Shoe (now Genesco); Jerrold Electronics; Standard Oil of Ohio. For the reason given in (a), these figures cannot be broken, down. The total value of assets divested as a result of the Section 7 actions in the 19 FTC cases found in (a) is $128,809,000. Note that this figures does not include any figures for the cases excluded in (a). The prices comprising this total are all market prices paid for the divested assets. For the reason given in-(a), these figures cannot be broken down. The total value of assets divested as a result of the Section 7 actions in the 13 Department of Justice cases found in (b) is $199,085,000. Note that this figure does not include any figure for the cases excluded in (b). The prices comprising this total are all market prices paid for the divested assets. For the reason given in (a), these figures cannot. be broken down. 279 ***** APPENDIX» C 280 281 Average Time Spans Number of Months from Acquisition to Government Complaintl FTC Sample Department of Justice Sample Automatic Canteen 30 American Cyanamid 54 Brillo 10 American Radiator 3 Continental Baking 46 Anheuser—Busch 8 Crown Zellerbach 8 Bethlehem Steel 0 Diamond Crystal 23 Brown Shoe -6 Farm Journal —3 Continental Can 0 Gulf Oil 9 Diebold —l Hooker Chemical 42 Gamble—Skogmo 20 International Paper 0 General Shoe 2 Leslie Salt 24 Hertz 31 MMM 48 Hilton 6 National Dairy 41 Jerrold 38 National Sugar 13 Lucky Lager 8 Reynolds Metals 16 Maremont 1 Scott Paper 32 Ryder 24 Scovill 11 Owens—Illinois 2 Simpson Timber 41 Schenley 2 Spalding 0 Standard of Ohio 0 Union Bag & Paper 0 Union Carbide 7 Vendo l 399 1 2 Number of Months from Acquisition to Divestiturel Automatic Canteen 51 American Cyanamid 101 Brillo 124 American Radiator 71 Continental Baking 6O Anheuser—Busch :4 Crown Zellerbach 130 Brown Shoe % Diamond Crystal 41 Continental Can 9 Farm Journal 15 Gamble—Skogmo 33 Gulf Oil 73 Hertz lg Hooker Chemical 40 Hilton 57 International Paper 7 Ryder . . 102 Leslie Salt 83 Owens—IllinOis MMM 62 National Dairy 125 National Sugar 71 Scovill 20 Spalding 94 Union Carbide 83 638 1079 1In some cases, where a series of acquis1tgonsoprmonths divestitures was involved in the action, the num er recorded above is an average of the series. LIBRA IES RSITY NIVE 6 5 0 3 0 3 9 2 1 3 ATE U \IHIHWIWIIIHIH 579 1