JNTERNATJDN‘AL momma FLU: Thesis for the Degree of? Ph. D ‘ ‘ :w - K. r MICHIGAN S ATE UNIVERSITY 2,. V : MILTON ES'BITI’? ’ " _ '_ _. . , ; 1970 “ : g: ‘ ; . . . ‘ - - .r . V ’V‘ 1 p‘fl..a~..,’ v I ..,. 'J .1 ... .. - -.u. 3.}:7F-v ... . u‘ v; con u "A'.;,".., n , ‘ 7 9' '1 A .,._ no: -1? I: “W‘s" 1", I” LIBP zY " UnIVcI 5y This is to certify that the thesis entitled INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS AND DOMESTIC ECONOMIC FLUCTUATION: THE UNITED STATES DURING THE 1830's presented by MILTON ESBITT has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for 3101’ professor Date November I 9 , ABSTRACT INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS AND DOMESTIC ECONOMIC FLUCTUATION: THE UNITED STATES DURING THE 1830's BY Milton Esbitt This dissertation shows how important components in the structure of the American economy and the economic relationships between America and Great Britain enabled economic disturbances on one side of the Atlantic to be transmitted to the other. In examining the structural elements of the Ameri- can economy two questions arose the treatment of which in previous works was found to be incomplete. What were the effects of the fiscal and monetary policies of the Jackson- Van Buren administrations on the economy? Secondly, what was the relationship between changes in the supply of specie and changes in the money supply, especially bank money and what were the causes of these specie inflows in the mid-1830's? The dissertation is divided into four parts. The first focused on the structural elements which made the Milton Esbitt American economy receptive to external disturbances. Attne- tion was placed on the financing of the Anglo-American trade. The second part examined the effects of the fiscal and monetary policies of the federal government on the per- formance of banks. The third part deals with the Panic of 1837, the immediate events that led to it and the recovery process which followed. The final section covers the deflation period of 1839-1844, its causes and the forces which brought it to an end. A comparison of the 1839-1844 deflation with others of the ante-bellum period concludes the dissertation. Three hypotheses were tested. The first examined the relationship between the British money market and Anglo-American trade. The results were inconclusive pri- marily because of a lack of sufficient data. The second hypothesis examined the relationship between changes in the supply of specie and changes in the supply of money. It was shown that there was no support for the often assumed relationship between these two variables. Regression analy- ses using annual data and first differences were used in testing these hypotheses. The final hypothesis dealt with the question of whether Deposit banks performed differently than other banks and the factors contributing to the dif- ferences. Deposit banks in general did pursue a more expansionary lending.policy than nonrdeposit banks and nmwements in Treasury deposits were more important than Milton Esbitt movements in specie in explaining this difference. A series of Chi square tests were used for this hypothesis. A large number of aggregate and disaggregate series dealing with both the American and British economies were used. New series were developed for American foreign exchange rates as well as domestic exchange rates. Esti- mates were also developed for the condition of Deposit and non-deposit banks in the various states and the major cities. The dissertation showed that given the structure of the Anglo-American trade and particularly the relation- ships between American and.British money and capital markets, economic disturbances were transmitted from one country to the other. The financial panic of 1837 was mainly due to pressures eminating from Great Britain but aggravated by internal factors in America. The collapse of the British money and capital markets in 1839 and the cotton market brought down the superstructure of Anglo—American trade. This in turn led to the deflation in America which lasted until 1844. INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS AND DOMESTIC ECONOMIC FLUCTUATION: THE UNITED STATES DURING THE 1830's BY Milton Esbitt A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1970 CD Copyright by MILTON ESBITT 1971 LIST OF LIST OF Chapter I. II. III. IV. TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLES O O O O O I O O O O O O APPENDICES . O O O O O O O O 0 INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . The Existing Analysis . . . . The Anglo-American Economies and the Transmission of Economid Disturbances . BANKING AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY DURING 1833 AND 1834 . . . . . . . . . . . The Second Bank of the United States and State Banks . . . . the Banking and Economic Activity During "Biddle' s Contraction" . . . . . . . . . CREDIT, MONEY AND SPECIE IN THE 1830's . Domestic Trade and Credit . . . . . Anglo-American Trade and Credit . . . Specie Flows and the Money Supply . . The Federal Government and the Supply of Money and Credit 1834- 1835 . . . . . . . Appendix to Chapter Three . . . . . THE GROWTH OF AGGREGATE DEMAND IN THE MID-1830'S Cotton and the American Economy in the Mid- 1839' s . . . . . Specialization, Urbanization and the Growth in the Mid-West and East . . . . . State Governments and the Growth of Transportation Infrastructure . . . . ii Page iv viii 14 15 30 36 36 44 48 69 80 83 83 89 97 Chapter Page V. THE END OF PROSPERITY . . . . . . . . . 110 Federal Fiscal and Monetary Policies in 1836 . 112 The New York Money Market in the Last Half of 1836 . . . . . . 146 The British Money and Commodity Markets During 1836 . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 VI. COTTON, SPECIE AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 1837 168 Grain, Cotton and the Anglo-American Money Markets . . . . . . . . 169 Suspension of the New York City Banks . . . 186 VII. THE AFTERMATH OF THE PANIC: DISLOCATION AND RECOVERY O O O O O O O O O O O O O 2 O 0 Dislocation and Its Economic Costs . . . 200 The Movement Towards Recovery in the United States 0 O O O O I O O O O O O 212 Resumption and Recovery . . . . . . . . 227 VIII. THE BRITISH MARKETS AND THE PANIC OF 1839 . . 255 The British and Continental Markets: Grains and Specie . . . . . . . . . . 256 The End of the Recovery: America in 1839 . . 265 The End of an Era: The Panic of 1839 . . . 276 IX. THE BECALMED YEARS: 1840-1843 . . . . . . 292 Reaching a Temporary Botton, 1840 . . . . 293 The Revival of Late 1840 and 1841 . . . . 299 The American Economy Reaches Botton: 1842— 1843 I O O I O O O O O O O O O 309 The Path to Recovery: 1843-1844 . . . . . 317 The 1839- 1843 Recession in Historical PerSpective . . . . . . . . . . . . 328 X. CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . 345 Excess Demand and Economic Growth . . . . 345 A Summary of the 1833-1843 Period . . . . 347 Concluding Comments . . . . . . . . . 359 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 363 APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 381 iii Table 2.1. 3.3. 4.1. LIST OF TABLES Comparison of the Second Bank of the United States and the Safety Fund Banks of New York State, Major Assets and Liabilities, 1831-1834 . . . . . . . . . . . . Major Assets and Liabilities of the Second Bank of the United States, Monthly August 1833-0Ct0ber 1834 o o o o o o o o 0 Major Assets and Liabilities, Banks of Massachusetts, Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, North Carolina, New York City, and the Second Bank of the United States, 1833- 1834 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Per cent of the Variation in the Money Supply and Bank Money Explained by Variations in the Total Supply of Specie and Bank Specie Holding, 1830-1845 . . . . . . . . . Percentage Change in Major Assets and Liabilities State Banks by Region, 1835-1837 . . . . . . . . . . . . Percentage Change in Major Assets and Liabilities of Banks in Selected States and Cities, 1834-1837 . . . . . . . . Per cent Distribution of State Debts Out- standing in 1838 by Purposes for which Incurred . . . . . . . . . . . . Percentage Changes in Selected Economic Series, 1830-1836 . . . . . . . . . . . . Capital Stock and United States Treasury Deposits of Deposit Banks Around June 1, 1936 O O O O O O C O O O O O O O The Relationship Between Changes in United States Treasury Deposits and the Major Assets and note Circulation of Deposit Banks, June- December 1836 . . . . . . . . . . . iv Page 16 21 27 6O 66 67 99 104 113 115 Table 5.3. 8.1. Interstate Transfer Drafts Issued and Payable Between June 23, 1836 and December 15, 1836 . The Relationship Between Net Interstate Transfer Flows and Changes in the Major Assets and Note Circulation of Deposit Banks Between June-August, 1836 and October 24-November 7, 1836 . . . . . . The Relationship Between Net Interstate Transfer Flows Necessitated by the Dis- tribution Act and Changes in the Major Assets and Note Circulation of Deposit Banks Between October 24-November 7, 1836 and December 1836 . . . . . . . . . Comparison of the Changes in Major Assets and Liabilities of Deposit Banks in Land Sale and Non-Land Sale States, July-October 1836 . . Distribution of Specie in State Banks, By Region, 1835-1836 . . . . . . . . Major Assets and Liabilities of Deposit Banks New York City July 1836-July 1837 . . . . The Amount of Treasury Deposits in the Several States During June and December, 1836, and the Amounts Due and Received by the States Under Sections 12 and 13 of the Deposit Act of June 23, 1836 O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Amount of Money Transferred From New York City Deposit Banks for the First Three Payments of the Distribution . . . . . . . . . . Percentage Changes in Selected Price Series 1835—1838 . . . . . . . . . . . . Percentage Changes in Bank Lending, Specie Holdings and Current Demand Liabilities, Selected Banks, April 1837-June 1838 . . . Estimates of State Expenditures and Receipts, per Capita and Aggregate for All States 1830-1845 . . . . . . . . . . . . Average Annual Prices and Volume of Grain Imports United Kingdom, 1830-1845 . . . . Page 121 124 126 136 144 147 181 187 203 220 240 257 Table 8.2. 9.1. B-S. Percentage Changes in Selected United States Price Series, Monthly 1839 . . . . . . Major Assets and Liabilities of Selected Banks 1838-1840 . . . . . . . . . . . . Ratios of Current Demand Liabilities and Demand Deposits to Bank Specie Holdings in Selected Banks 1839 . . . . . . . . Prices of United States State of New York, and New York City Bonds at New York City February 1842-MarCh 1843 o o o o o o o o o 0 Imports Into the Port of New York, 1833-1844 Comparison of Three Ante-Bellum Economic Disturbances, 1818-1822, 1837-1843, 1857-1860 . . . . . . . . . . . . United States Balance of Payments, 1830-1845 Federal Receipts, Expenditures, Annual and Gross Deficits and Surpluses, 1830-1845 . . Receipts From Public Land Sales by the United States, Quarterly, 1830-1845 . . . . . . United States Exports of Flour, Corn and Meal, 1830-1845 . . . . . . . . . . . . Interstate Transfer Drafts Issued for the Distribution of the Surplus Revenue . . . Estimates of Major Assets, All United States Banks, 1829, 1833-1845 . . . . . . . . Estimates of Major Liabilities, All United States Banks, 1829, 1833-1845 . . . . . Selected Assets and Liabilities of Federal Deposit Banks, 1834-1837 . . . . . . . Comparison of Percentage Changes in Major Assets and Liabilities of Selected Deposit Banks and Banks of the States or Cities in which they are Located, 1834-1847 . . . . Monetary Conditions in the United Kingdom, 1830-1845 . . . . . . . . . . . vi Page 266 270 280 319 323 333 383 384 385 386 387 389 390 391 392 (1) k0 43 Table B- 6. B- 7. B- 8. B- 9. B-10. B-11. B-12. B-13. B-14. B-15. C- 1. C- 2. C- 3. C- 4. C- 5. Estimates of the United States Money Supply, 1833-1845 . . . . . . . . . . . . . Average Short-Term Interest Rates in London and New York Money Markets and the Bank of England Discount Rate, Monthly, January 1834-December 1844 O O O I O I O O O O O O O 0 Foreign Exchange Rates, Dollars and Pounds, January 1834-December 1843 . . . . . . . Value of the Pound Sterling in Dollars . . . The Condition of the New York City Banks, July 1834-rday 1844 o o o o o o o o o o 0 Major Assets and Liabilities of the Leading New York City Deposit Banks, February-July, 1837 . Quarterly Indicators of Monetary Conditions in the United Kingdom, 1833-1842 . . . . . Major Liabilities of the New York City Banks, January 1837-May 1838 . . . . . . . . . The Condition of the New York Safety Fund Banks, 1831-1837 . . . . . . . . . . Prices of Domestic Exchange at New York, January 1835-September, 1842 . . . . . . Estimates of United States Cotton Prices, 1830—1845 0 o o o o o o o o o o o 0 United States Cotton Production and Consumption, 1830-1845 . . . . . . . Anglo-American Trade, 1830-1845 . . . Cotton Consumption and Production, United States and the United Kingdom, Percentage Changes, 1830-1845 . . . . . . . . . . Monthly Prices of Short-Staple Cotton, New Orleans and England, January 1834-January 1845 O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 vii Page 395 396 399 402 403 404 405 406 407 408 412 413 414 415 416 4- LIST OF APPENDICES Appendix Page Appendix A . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 382 Appendix B . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 388 Appendix C . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 411 viii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The Existing Analysis The third decade of the nineteenth century was one of change, sometimes turbulent, for the American economy as well as for American political life. Most of this decade was passed under the warmth of good times.1 The last three years and the first three of the next decade were times of instability which, by 1839, developed into a depression, supposedly second in magnitude to that of the "Great Depression" of this century.2 Most of the works dealing with the economy during the period focused on the conflict, in which Jackson and Biddle were the star actors in a many plotted drama, pitting the new money interests of Wall Street and the old of Philadelphia, the supporters of banking which would aid public and private groups in the construction of develop- mental investments such as the transportation infrastruc- ture, and those who believed that banks should continue gmimarily as "commercial" banks.3 Finally, we had those who supported a hard currency, one based on specie and ébvoid of bank notes not completely redeemable in specie, amithose who, for whatever reason, believed that banks should have the privilege--some held the right to issue bank notes.4 Besides the works dealing with the political-economic conflict over banking, there have been but two which have dealt with the depression with the use of economic analysis.5 In 1954, R.C.O. Matthews in his, "A Study in Trade Cycle History," placed a large part of the blame for the depressed economic conditions prevalent in the United Kingdom and the United States during the last years of the 1830's and the first of the 1840's on actions emanating from the United States.6 As we shall see, he underestimates the crucial role which the money and capital markets of the United Kingdom--mainly centered in London--had in determining the economic health of the Anglo-American economies. Walter B. Smith, writing a year earlier had recognized this dependence. Easy money in England in the early 1830's stimulated the merchandise trade by making merchantile credits available to American merchants, by facilitating a period of prosperity in England which rebounded to the benefit of American producers, and lastly by touching off a wave of loans to American States and corpora- tions which brought prosperity to the United States and also assisted the process of paying for these imports.7 Peter Temin in his recently published book, "The Jacksonian Economy," has shown that much of the works dealing with this period overstated the importance of the United States Bank and the policies of the Jackson and Van Buren 'mhunistrations in the economic fluctuations of the 1830's. Pmmfly because of his stress on the use of aggregate monetary data, however, he moved to the opposite direction and, as we shall see in Chapters three to six, underestimated the effects of the fiscal and monetary policies of these admin- istrations on the American economy during these years. In his analysis Temin assumes that increases in the amount of specie available to the banks led to an expansion of the American money supply which in turn led to the growth of economic activity. This approach, however, implies that there was no problem as far as the demand for these lonable funds were concerned. As we shall show in this work there was an asymmetrical relationship between the availability of credit facilities and economic activity, an expanding supply was necessary for continued economic expansion, but the existence of such facilities did not necessarily ensure an expansion of economic activity. The Anglo-American Economies and the Transmission of Economic Disturbances During the 1830's and 1840's, the American economy was dependent on cotton exports for a majority of its foreign exchange earnings, and on the London money and capital markets for short-and-long-term international capital supplies.9 Moreover, these capital inflows were vital to the growth of the domestic money supply and credit markets. This work will examine how, given the structure of nglo-American trade and particularly the relationships Immween the American and British money and capital markets, economic disturbances could be transmitted from one country to the other. More specifically, by examining the relation- ships between the American and British economies and the mechanism which transmitted economic shocks from one country to the other, we will attempt to show that: (l) the mone- tary panic of 1837 was due mainly to pressures eminating from Great Britain but with internal factors in America aggravating the situation; (2) the collapse of the London money and capital markets in 1839 brought down with it the British cotton market and the superstructure of the Anglo- American trade, which in turn brought on the depression in America in late 1839. The severity and the length of the depression indicates that the structure of the American economy contained critical faults which enabled the shock waves from Great Britain to have such drastic effects on the American economy. These statements are in conflict with the conclusions of Matthews and in part those of Temin. This is primarily due to the fact that one's VieWpoint and eventually the con- clusions derived from a particular analytical study is shaped not only by when, but also by where in the causal process one enters.10 Matthews focused his attention on the British export industries and the relative importance of fluctuations in 'UmaAmerican market on this important sector of the British expnomy.ll But, as already noted, he overlooked the crucial role which the London money and capital markets played in financing British exports to the United States. An analysis is incomplete which states that the sharp drop in British exports to the United States was the primary cause of the 1839 downturn in Great Britain, when the decline in exports was mainly due to monetary conditions in Great Britain. Temin, as Matthews, does not fully taken into account the importance of the British money and capital markets to -the health of the British economy. It was the vitality of the British economy, especially its cotton textile industry; and on capital and money markets that permitted the continued expansion of the American economy. During the mid-1830's economic growth in the United States was characterized by an excess demand, at full employ- ment, for domestically produced goods. At the same time there was an excess demand for money needed to finance the growth in demand for goods. Both of these excess demands were met by an excess supply, in terms of the ability of the American market to absorb them, of securities which flowed across the Atlantic in ever increasing amounts during the mid-and late-1830's. The excess demand for goods grew out of the expanding cotton market, the willingness and ability of state and local governments to undertake vast internal improvement projects and the increasing specializa- 12 tion of the American economy. The British economy, its cxmton, its money and capital markets, and its manufacturing industries stood in the middle, purchasing American cotton and supplying the goods, and short-and-long-term credits needed by the expanding American economy. The Transmitting Mechanisms Disturbances could be transferred from one country to the other because of the relation between their respec- tive money supplies and capital markets. The American and British money supplies consisted mainly of Specie, bank notes, and demand deposits, the latter two supposedly con- vertible on demand into specie (gold and silver coins). Though the existing monetary systems in both countries resembled the gold standard in their adjustments to specie flows, there were differences of varying importance. The United States was legally on a bi-metallic standard though the Coinage Acts of 1834 and 1837 by over- valuing gold, soon resulted in the country's being on a defacto gold standard. The American mint ratio of 15 to l clashed with a ratio of about 15 1/2 to l prevailing on world markets so little gold came to it for coinage, and the United States was in effect on a silver standard. The Coinage Acts of 1834 and 1837 reversed this dis- parity by setting a new mint ratio of very nearly 16 to 1. Since the United States was now valuing silver less highly relative to gold than was the world market, little silver was offered for coinage, and the United States was in effect on a gold standard.13 An examination of specie imports and coinage both ‘before and after these acts casts doubt on this assertion Itmnzdoes indicate that silver did become relatively less important than it had been before 1834.14 The importance of these acts lies in the fact that they, for all practical purposes tied the American and British money supplies to- gether through what has been called the specie-flow mecha- nism. The two most common types of gold standard systems-- perhaps specie standard would be a more accurate term--are the 100% reserve system and the fractional reserve system.15 In the former there is a one to one relationship between the issuance of bank demand liabilities--banknote and demand deposits--and the supply of specie. In the latter, bank demand liabilities are issued in some multiple of the specie supply. During the period under study both the United States and the United Kingdom had fractional reserve sys- tems, but as there was no single note issuing body in the United States or legally specified ration, there was no one particular ratio which applied.16 Under a fractional reserve system fluctuations in specie would cause fluctuations in the amount of bank notes in circulation though it is important to realize that these movements of reserves and bank notes do not necessarily have to follow one upon the other. Willett shows that variations in bank specie holdings did not cause a con- comitant immediate change in the banks current demand liabilities.l7 Normally with a specie standard, a country with a deficit in its balance on current account tended to lose specie. The United States, however, between fiscal years 1832 and 1837 inclusively, incurred a deficit on current account every year while at the same time importing specie each year as we see from Appendix Table A-1. The United States was able to do this because of its ability to borrow both short-and-long-term capital in the London and to a lesser degree Continental markets. As long as the United States continued to have access to these credit markets the balance of payments could be balanced through short-and-long-term capital imports. Avoided therefore, were massive specie outflows and an economic contraction which would have been the alter- native if it had not been for the capital inflows. These capital flows were crucial, as we shall see, to the economic stability of the United States during this period. In the spring of 1837, American and British firms in the Anglo-American trade were unable to obtain new short- term credits, or to refinance credits due for payment. The resulting scramble for liquidity, combined with the exporta- tjrni of specie arising from the exchange rates being forced “no the specie export point, due to a lack of cotton bills, proved too much for the Eastern banks. The New York City banks were under the greatest pressure, not only losing specie tnIEngland but also losing specie because of the distribution of the Federal surplus. The end result was the nmnuetary panic and the bank suspensions of 1837. By the middle of 1839, the flow of specie from Great Britain to the Continent, to pay for grain imports necessi- tated by poor harvests, produced a contraction in the London money markets which was more severe than that of the winter 18 This monetary stringency contributed and spring of 1837. in large part to the collapse of the British cotton market. The resulting collapse of the structure which supported the Anglo-American trade, especially the drying up of the long- term capital inflows to the United States, goes a long way towards explaining the causes of the depression which over- whelmed the United States in late 1839. In the next nine chapters we will examine those events and processes on both sides of the Atlantic which brought about the expansion of the American economy in the mid-1830's; the financial panics of 1837 and 1839, and the deflation which overtook the American economy in 1839 and lasted until 1844. Chapters II through IV will cover the period between 1833 and 1836; the so-called "Biddle's Panic," and the boom of 1834-1836. Attention will be focused on the structural elements which made the American economy so receptive to external disturbances eminating from the Eastern side of the Atlantic. In Chapter V"w ‘will see what effects the fiscal and monetary policies of the Jackson administration had on the American economy during these years and especially the events of 1836. 10 The Panic of 1837 and the factors bringing it about will be examined in Chapter VI. Chapters VII and VIII will examine the recovery period of 1838 and 1839 as well as the events leading to the panic of the latter year. The deflation period of 1838-1843 and the possible causes of the upturn in late 1843 and 1844 will be the subject of Chapter IXH In Chapter X we conclude by reexamining the ground we have covered and the conclusions we have drawn from this work showing the nature and causes of the economic fluctuation experienced by the American economy during these years. Throughout this work we will use not only informa- tion dealing with the economy as a whole such as wholesale commodity prices series, foreign trade statistics, land sales and estimates of the money supply; but also data dealing with one particular sector or section of the economy such as canal traffic, price series for particular cities and the condition of banks in various cities and states. We use both types of data not only because they provide a check on each others reliability but also, and more impor- tantly, because the latter type of information enables us to examine significant develOpments in the economic history of this period which cannot be seen by using just the esti- mates of over-all economic activity. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER I 1Recent research has shown that the down-turn of 1833- 1834 was of less real magnitude than originally thought. See Jacob P. Meerman, "The Climax of the Bank War: Biddle's Contraction, 1833-34," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 71 (August, 1962): Pp. 378-388. 2Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, The Great Contraction (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965), p. 3. We shall examine the magnitude of the "depression" in Chapter IX. 3For the politics of the period see Glyndon G. Van Deusen, The Jacksonian Era, 1828-1848 (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1957), and Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Age of Jackson (Boston: Little Brown and Company, 19457: For the Bank War and the general economic conditions of the period see Walter B. Smith, Economic Aspects of the Second Bank of the United States (Cambridge: Harvard Uni- versity Press, 1953), and Frank Otto Gatell, The Jacksonian and the Money Powers, 1829-1840 (The Berkeley Series in American History, Chicago: Rand McNally and Company, 1967). 4For the monetary theories and banking practices prevalent before the Civil War see Harry E. Miller, Banking Theories in the United States Before 1860 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1927); Joseph Dorfman, The Eco- nomic Mind in American Civilization (2 Vols., London: George G. Harrap and Company, Ltd., 1947), II, Chap. 23. Dorfman notes that William Gouz, one of the leading monetary writers of the period believed that there should be no bank notes at all, just Specie, p. 608. Fritz Redlich, The Molding of American Banking (2 Vols., New York: Hafner Publishing Co., 1947, 1953). Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Age of Jackson, Chap. 10. 5Ira Ryner, "On the Crisis of 1837, 1847, and 1857, in.England, France, and the United States," University of Eggaska Studies, Vol. V #27 (1905). Reginald C. McGrane, TflggPafiIc of 1837: Some Financial Problems of the Jacksonian 251(Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1924). 11 12 Samuel Rezneck, "The Social History of an American Depres- sion, 1837-1843," American Historical Review, Vol. XL, No. 4 (July, 1935), pp. 662-687. Note that all these works do not differentiate between 1837 and 1839. 6R.C.O. Matthews, A Study in Trade Cycle History (Cambridge: Cambridge Press, 1954). 7Smith, p. 87. 8Peter Temin, The Jacksonian Economy (New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1969). It must be noted in passing that the accuracy of the aggregate series used are never seriously questioned. 9We will not examine directly the question of what role cotton played in fostering economic growth in the United States during the period through the process of export based growth. For earlier "strong" statement and a later modified View of this position by its leading proponent see Douglass C. North, The Economic Growth of the United States: 1790-1860 (New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1966), pp. 68-74, and Douglass C. North, Growth and Welfare in the American Past (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1966): p. 84. 10It would be difficult to convince most historians that World War I would not have occurred if there had been no assassination at Sarajevo. 11See the criticism of Matthews' conclusions in Jeffrey G. Williamson, American Growth and the Balance of Payments: 1820-1913 (Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press, 1964), pp. 204-205. 12Williamson, pp. 185-186; Thomas D. Willett, "Inter- national Specie Flows and American Monetary Stability, 1834- 1860," The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 8 (March, 1968), pp. 28-50, especially pp. 32-34. ‘13Leland B. Yeager, International Monetarijelations (New York: Harper and Row, 1966), p. 252. 14See George R. Taylor, The Transportation Revolu- tion: 1815-1860 (New York: Holt, Rinehart, Winston and Co., 1951), pp. 328-329. For information on specie imports and cxfinage, see Hunt's Merghants' Magazine, March, 1844, p. 249; April, 1844, p. 376. ' 15 See Yeager, Ch. 4. 13 16Between 1830, to 1833, the ratio of specie to current demand liabilities, bank notes and demand deposits, for the Second Bank of the United States varied between a low of 17 per cent and a high of 32 per cent. Between 1834 and 1839, it varied from 17 per cent to 54 per cent. For Boston banks the comparable figures are nine per cent to 21 per cent and 10 per cent to 23 per cent. Smith, p. 47. For an interesting attempt to explain why these ratios varied see Thomas D. Willett, "International Specie Flows and American Monetary Stability, 1834-1860," The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 28 (March, 1968), pp. 28-50. We will see in Chapter III, that reserve ratios as now understood, did not apply to most banks in the United States during this period. 17 Willett, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 28, pp. 39-40 0 18During the last half of 1839, the average market rate of discount in London and the Bank of England discount rate reached the highest levels for the fifteen years between 1830 and 1845. Matthews, pp. 199, 201; and Thomas Tooke, History of Prices, and of the State of the Circulation, From 1839 to 1847 (London: Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans, 1848), pp. 440-442. CHAPTER II BANKING AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY DURING 1833 AND 1834 Except for the slight recession of late 1833 and 1834, the period between 1833 and 1837 was one of economic growth and prosperity. This was the result of economic and noneconomic factors, both domestic and foreign, which interacted to bring about a rapid growth in America's demand for goods and services. This growth in demand was for both consumption and investment purposes. But only part of it could be met from domestic sources. Generating the demand and providing at least some of the output needed to supply it was the increasing eco- nomic specialization of the American economy. The two most visible signs of this specialization in the 1830's were the expanding cotton market and the boom in the construction of canals and later, railroads. The changing and growing money and credit structure in America combined with massive specie imports to finance the growth in aggregate demand and supply. In this and the two chapters that follow we will mmmine the 1834-1837 boom period and analyze the factors, bOUIreal and monetary which brought it about. This chapter 14 15 will examine the "Bank War," in which the Second Bank of the United States lost its role as the fiscal agent for the federal government. Our attention will center on the effects which this had on the economy during 1833 and early .1834. We will also look at the probable effects of the "Bank War" on the structure and performance of the banking ' system. Chapter III will explore how the credit and bank- ing system of the United States and its relationship with that of Great Britain supported the growing volume of trade in these years. Finally, in Chapter IV we will conclude our analysis of the boom by seeing how increasing economic specialization supplied the impetus for the economic pros- perity of the mid-1830's. The Second Bank of the United States and the State Banks The Second Bank of the United States and the Supply of Bank Moneprrior to 1833 The Second Bank'bf the United States was able, by virtue not-only of its size but more importantly because of its position as the fiscal agency of the United States Treasury, to control the quantity of notes issued by the state chartered banks; In Table 2.1 we have a comparison of the size of the Bank in relation to that of all the Safety Fund Banks.of New York State., (See page 16.) Commercial banks when extending loans or discounting cmmmrcial paper issued bank notes or created demand deposits. These current demand liabilities could come into the 16 TABLE 2.1.--Comparison of the Second Bank of the United States and the Safety Fund Banks of New York State, Major Assets and Liabilities, (Millions of Dollars) 1831-1834.a Current Bank Ex- Bank and Loans and Circu- Depositsb Demand Specie pansion Date Discounts lation Liabili- Multi- ties plierC (2 + 3) 1831 SBUS $44.1 $16.2 $6.8 $23 $10.8 2.1 NYS 11.2 5.9 1.6 7.5 .4 18.7 SBYS/NYS 394% 274% 425% 307% 2700% 11% 1832 SBUS $66.3 $21.3 $2.6 $23.9 $ 7.0 3.4 NYS 32.8 12.0 5.8 17.8 1.7 10.5 SBUS/NYS 202% 177% 45% 134% 412% 32% 1833 SBUS $61.7 $17.5 $2.3 $19.8 $ 8.9 2.2 NYS 35.6 12.2 7.9 20.1 1.8 11.2 SBUS/NYS 173% 143% 29% 98% 494% 20% 1834 SBUS $54.9 $19.2 $5.1 $24.3 $10.0 2.4 NYS 43.7 15.4 8.4 23.8 2.2 10.8 SBUS/NYS 126% 125% 61% 102% 454% 22% aJanuary l of each year. b Private deposits. CRatio of Current Demand Liabilities divided by the amount of specie. Sources: The reciprocal of this is known as the reserve ratio. SBUS: The Statistical Historyppf the United States From Colonial Times to the Present Publishers, New York Safety Fund: Inc., 1965), p. 623. (Stamford, Conn.: Series X Robert C. Chaddock, The Safety Fund Fairfield 6, 12, 15. Banking System in New York, 1829-1866, U.S. National Monetary Commission 6lst Congress, pp. 296-297. 2nd Session, Document NO . 581! 1910: 17 possession of the S.B.U.S. in one of two ways. First, the S.B.U.S. acquired these current demand liabilities through the normal course of its banking operations, expecially in 'the domestic and foreign exchange markets, in both of which it was dominant.1 Second, being the fiscal agency of the Treasury, its holdings of state bank notes and checks increased as a result of the inflow of government deposits, at its various branches, arising out of the payment of import duties and land sales revenue. As long as the Bank maintained its position as a net creditor of the state banks it was able to control the money issues of the latter by presenting for redemption in specie or specie funds, to the issuing banks the bank notes or checks which the bank held.2 The loss of these reserves by the state banks, given the nature of a fractional reserve banking system, could cause an indirect but greater con— traction of the money Supply. The bank, on the other hand, could find itself a net debtor to the state banks during periods of government debt retirement when in its role as fiscal agent for the treasury it redeemed these debts. It was also in such a position when it extended its own loans and discounts more than the state banks did. Walter B. Smith believed that the Bank was normally a creditor until the middle of 1834.3 Gallatin, on the other hand, wrote tmflzthe bank had lost its ability to control the money SnIPply earlier, during 1832-1833, 18 _ When its discounts and other investments were increased from fifty-five to sixty-five millions. It is obvious that it is only by keeping its discounts at a lower rate--in relation to capita1--than those of the state banks that these can be its debtors, and that it is only by enforcing the payment of the bal- ances that it can keep them within bounds and thus regulate the currency.4 How effective was the Bank in controlling the money issues of state banks? Furthermore, how important was its portfolio transactions to the health of the money markets? It should not be forgotten that the Bank by varying the size and composition of its portfolio,5 could and did influence the condition of the money markets in the United States. Though the answers to these questions--if they are obtainable--are interesting in and of themselves, they are necessary to an understanding of the importance of the Bank to the monetary systems and especially the relation- ship between the elimination of the Bank as a regulator of the monetary system and the monetary eXpansion of the mid-1830's. The simplest way of measuring the effectiveness of the S.B.U.S. in regulating the money supply is to compare the rates of monetary growth before and after 1834. Assum- ing for the moment that we have sufficient information for this task, this procedure means that if the annual rate of monetary expansion was X per cent in the years between, KW'1830 and 1833, and it increased to X + N per cent in tmaperiod 1834 to 1837, the increase was due to the removal OEthe S.B.U.S. as the regulator of the state banks. 19 This procedure, however, first assumes that the only significant changes in the monetary system of the United States as well as the economy in general centered around the changing role of the S.B.U.S. As we will see in this and the next chapter, this assumption is incorrect. This line of reasoning furthermore assumes--and this point is often overlooked--that even if the S.B.U.S.‘s role was not altered, it Would not have changed its banking policies in response to changing economic conditions, especially the cotton boom and the large inflow of specie and British capital. We can, on the other hand, reject these assump- tions and assume that the monetary expansion of the mid- 1830's would have been of the observed magnitude regardless of whether the bank was rechartered or not. What then do we do with this N per cent difference? Probably the best eXpedient is to accept the fact that we cannot realisticayly estimate what the monetary expansion would have been if the S.B.U.S. had been rechartered. It should be noted however, that without one bank acting as the fiscal agency for the Treasury, there was no nation- wide, centralized control over the issuance of bank money. The Bank War and Biddle's Contraction On July 10, 1832, President Jackson vetoed the bill for rechartering the Bank.6 It was not, however, until the and of the following summer, after the reelection of Jackson 20 that "Biddle's Contraction," the S.B.U.S.‘S response to the governments actions, started. Toward the end of July, 1833, rumors were circulat- ing in Washington about the plans being made to remove government deposits from the bank. On September 20th, the semi-official Washington Globe printed the following: We are authorized to state that the deposits of the public money will be changed from the Bank of the United States to the state banks, as soon as necessary arrangements can be made for that purpose, and that 'it is believed, they can be completed in Baltimore, Philadelphia, New York, and Boston in time to make the change by the first of October, and perhaps sooner, if circumstances Should render an earlier action nec- essary on the part of the government. It is contem- plated, we understand, not to remove, at once, the whole of the public money, now on deposit in the Bank of the United States, but . . . it shall be gradually withdrawn by the usual operations of the government. Action soon followed rumor for on September 26, an order was issued telling the collectors of the revenue not to deposit government funds in the S.B.U.S.8 During the month of October, public deposits including those of state and local governments at the S.B.U.S. fell by seventeen per cent. During the late summer of 1833, prior to the official actions of the Treasury department, the S.B.U.S. began to prepare for such actions. In August 1833, the bank placed a lid on further discounting on notes, limited bills of exchange to ninety days and permitted its western offices tp purchase only short-term domestic bills drawn on Atlantic coast cities. This last action increased the bank's claims 21 .mv one wv moESHo> .uoumflmom Hmcoflpmz moaflz IHcD .mofleocoom mo ucoEuumdoo .coflumuuommao .o.nm poLmHHQSQSDV CH mcoflumsuosHm oHEocoom mo muoommd meow .hmm .ovaImHmH .m .Amoxoe wo xpflmuo> .mmnmum owned: may "napouu xcmm cmofluoE< ppm moHQNU opoue nmfluflum .mCOmumm CMHupa oxusm .vmmImmm .md .nH ucoEsooo mumcom .coflmmom ppm .mmouocou pumm .oumcom .mmoumcou .m.: "moUMSOm .mxcmn oumum ou mcflzo poz u I .osp uoz n +b .mcHUCSOH mo omsmoob Hmuou Hmnqo uoc xmzo m.~m m. I m.vm o.mH m.m m.o o.m m.am m.mH o.ov m.oa H.mm «mma .uoo H.~m v. I m.vm m.mH o.m m.m N.m o.Ho m.ma H.>v ~.NH m.vm .umom m.mm m. I m.m~ m.ma m.m m.w m.~ m.mw m.ma n.mv m.ma n.vm .ms< m.- e. + m.m~ m.ma m.m m.w m.m m.mm m.ma o.am m.ma v.vm >Hsn m.m~ m.H+ N.mm m.mH o.m m.m n.m m.vm m.mH m.~m m.nH n.em econ m.mm v.H+ m.m~ m.mH «.0H 0.5 m.m m.vm N.HH n.mm m.mH ~.mm we: >.vm m. + m.>~ m.nH H.0H m.h m.m o.mo m.oa m.vm n.mH H.mm Hflumc w.mm H. + «.mm m.mH m.m m.n m.m o.mw v.0H «.mm m.ma v.hm nouns o.mm ¢.H+ H.mm m.mH m.m h.w H.m m.mm m.oa m.vm m.nH m.>m .nom m.mm m.H+ ~.om N.ma o.HH n.m m.e m.vm 0.0H m.vm m.ma m.mm vmma .cwh «.mm m.m+ m.om m.ma o.mH m.m N.m ~.vm m.m v.qm n.ma m.mm .ooa m.mm v.m+ o.vm m.mH m.ma m.h m.m m.nm m.oa N.>m H.ma H.Hv .>oz H.h~ m.m+ o.nm H.mH m.nH o.m m.m m.an n.oa m.om v.5H m.mv .uoo m.n~ m. + o.nm v.ma m.ma v.m N.m m.~n m.oa n.~o m.mH v.mv .udmm o.mm m.om m.mH n.5H H.0H w.h m.en o.oa m.vm m.om N.mv mmma .ms< coflumasouflu pmxcmm .nmflq muflmo muflmo muflmo ofloomm w mmucsoo mHHHm a muflmomoo oumum pcmEoo cofluwa Imoo Idea Imoo mucsoomflo Imflo a oHumm mucsoo oum>flum Eoum upon Isouflu Hobos oum> UHH mcmoq mo ofloomm mcmoq IEoo Imflo open 0:0 IHDU IHHm Insm HmuOB Hmuoe imueaaoe mo meoeaaflei .emma H88.8 ImmmH umsms< .NHSHCOZ .mmumum Umuflcs OLD Mo xcmm Ucoomm mnu m0 mmflpflaflnmflq Ucm mummmd Hoflmzll.m.m mqmdB 22 on Eastern banks. These were needed when the government deposits were drawn.down making the Bank a debtor of (state) banks receiving government deposits. On September 24th, the ordergiven to the Western branches was extended to certain Eastern and Southern branches.9 Though its holdings of domestic bills of exchange continued to fall, no action was taken on discounts until ,October 8th, when the bank's board of directors ordered a reduction of $5.8 million in diScounts. This was followed on January 23, 1834 by another directive to cut discounts by an additional $3.3 million. Between August 1833, when the S.B.U.S. first started its curtailment policies and July 1834, when the S.B.U.S. ended this policy, its loans and discounts fell by $13.2 million.10 With the vetoing of its charter renewal by Jackson, the Second Bank of the United States, to prepare itself for the transfer of the Treasury deposits to the state banks, curtailed its lending activities. During this period of contraction which lasted from August 1833 to July 1834, the bank's loans and discounts fell by about twenty-one per cent. In the next section we will see how the banking system.and the economy in general fared during this period. Our task is made more difficult, however, by the near record specie imports of 1834, which went mostly into expanded bank 23 IBanking‘andEconomic Activity During ”Biddle's Contraction" The effects of the actions of the S.B.U.S. on the banking system were of two types: first the response of the other banks to the curtailed leading activities of the S.B.U.S.; and secondly the possible effects which the transfer of the Treasury deposits had on the lending activi- ties of the state banks, both those that received these deposits and those which did not. It is the sum total of what did happen in the banking system, taken together with developments outside of it which produced the economic difficulties of late 1833 and 1834 which has been called "Biddle's Contraction." It is difficult to obtain a clear picture of how the banking system responded to the actions of the S.B.U.S. The first problem we face is the lack of sufficient data on aggregate bank lending during this period. The second and more important difficulty is the massive specie inflows during fiscal 1834 which minimized the contractionary ef- fects of the actions of the S.B.U.S. The available aggregate estimates of bank lending go only as far back as 1834 and these are not very complete. The data given includes estimates which had to be made for approximetely one-quarter of the state banks because they <fid.not submit returns. Though January 1, 1834 is given as the reporting date, many state banks filed reports with 24 their state governments months before this date and some- times a few months after.11 The second problem arises out of the massive specie inflows which took place during this period. This perhaps can be more clearly seen if we first attempt to hypothesize what would happen to the banking system in response to the curtailment policy of the S.B.U.S. assuming that there were no changes in the United States supply of specie. Assuming that the state banks did not alter their leading policies and that there was no significant change in the supply of specie in the United States, the curtail- ment of the S.B.U.S.‘s leading activities meant a contrac- tion in the supply of money. The extent of this contraction depends on and in what proportion loan repayments were made with the demand liabilities of the S.B.U.S. and the state banks. If the loans were repaid with checks drawn on the S.B.U.S., or its own bank notes, the contraction in the money supply consisted of a reduction in the current demand liabilities of the S.B.U.S. Repayments made with checks or bank notes of state banks, had the same direct effect on the money supply. Indirectly, however, there was a dif- ference. If loan repayment increased the net creditor position of the S.B.U.S. vis a vis the state banks, it 12 could redeem their current demand liabilities for specie. The reduction in specie reserves if not offset by fresh 25 inflows, could cause a multiple contraction in the current demand liabilities of the state banks. During the same period in which the S.B.U.S. cut back its loans and discounts by $13.2 million, its specie hold- 'ings increased by $2.8 million. If we assume that this increase was at the expenSe of the state banks or the non- banking sector of the economy without any compensating specie importation, the money supply must have contracted. The amount of the contractipn depended on the origin of the specie inflow to the S.B.U.S. If the specie came from the non-banking sector of the economy, the contraction of the money supply was equal to the amount of the specie transfer. If it came from the state banks either directly through redemption of current demand liabilities or indirectly through the public, there may have been a multiple contraction in the money supply. This occurred if banks reacted to specie losses by curtail- ing their own lending activities. Fortunately for the S.B.U.S. and the state banks there were massive specie imports during this time. In fiscal 1834, the United States had net specie imports of about $15.8 million compared to inflows of about $4.4 nullion in the previous fiscal year. Since the S.B.U.S. increased its specie holdings by $4.9 million during fiscal 1834, it is obvious that the increase in its holdings was not at the expense of the state banks in general. 26 What happened to the supply of money and credit during the period of the S.B.U.S.‘s contraction, given these specie inflows? Lacking aggregate data on bank lending for 1833 we are forced to use what fragmentary information is (available. This information is given in Table 2.3. While the S.B.U.S.‘s contraction may have induced a parallel move by the other Pennsylvania banks, those of New York City and Massachusetts expanded their lending activities but the absolute size of the S.B.U.S.‘s and Pennsylvania's contractions more than offset the expansion of theSe banks. The net effect was a decrease in the amount of credit available in the Eastern money markets. Interest rates on Short-term commercial paper in New York and BoSton which had averaged between five and one-half per cent and seven per cent during 1831-1832 and the first half of 1833, rose to 15 per cent by the end of the year and by the end of January 1834 they were at 24 per cent per annum. For the next ten months we find no rates listed but rather the following comments, "business unsettled, rates high and variable." By the end of 1834 the short- term interest rate had fallen to eight per cent. The money supply grew during 1834 and the means by which it grew indicate that state banks took up the slack left by the contractionary policies of the S.B.U.S. The wgney supply is estimated to have increased by $4.4 million during the year. This increase appears to have been entirely £27 .mnw canoe "mmumum teams: on» mo xcmm pcooom ma .m .mn .oz ucoeoooo .conmwm :uow .mumcoflmmHEEoo xcmm on» wo uuomom .xanEomm< .mumum xuo» 302 ">ufiu xuow 3oz .HHH .oz ucofisooo omsom .coflmmom can .mmouocoo zuom .omsom .mmoumcou .m.D "mwumum "mmousom .meumum coped: one we seem ecoudm one moesaoxme .coflumHsouflo cam muflmommp muo>fium mo Esme .mousmflm wmmzu SH pmtSHUCH no: mnt noficz amououca co mnemommc coumfia omam UcmHmH opozm can muuomsnommmmr .muflmomot Deanna tam oum>flum cow3uon mumflucoumwuflo won on mmou50m one .mxcmm ease Sumumm Spec snow 362 use use meumum capes: men «0 xcmm ecoomm one nod admoxmn .ccSOw on oasoo coflumEMONCA mflcu cofinz new .mxcmn >uflu xuo» 3oz Hospfl>flpCA acetoaoxo .mxcmp >Hco ecu one omonao nHI m.m~ «HI m.w mHI m.mH ov+ w.ma mva o.mv vmma .uoo H.>~ o.m H.ma h.oa o.oo mmmH .uoo .m.D opp mo xcom pcooom m~+ m.vH mm+ m.m , ma+ o.m ovm+ v.v wmm+ v.om mmma .coh N.HH 0.5 m.v o.H o.mm mmma .>oz mxcom pcsm Nuowmw .o.>.z ma+ >.v N + o.H mH+ n.m mm+ m.a ma + n.h vmwa .uoo H.v mm. H.m m.H m.> mmma .cmm oflmuoou o mm.H m + . me. m I mm. hmI mo. mmmI m.H vmwa ocsn mm.H ow. mm. vm. v.~ mmma mach .Hmu .oz mm+ m.m mm+ m.m o m.H nH+ we. we + o.m «mma .uoo m.m m.H m.H ow. N.m mmma .uoo .mH opocm mHI m.wa m I o.m emu w.m ma+ v.m woaI m.mm vmma .uoo ~.om m.m v.oH m.m w.Hm mmmH .uoo p.c:om m + m.mH Nm+ m.v v I e.e mm+ ~.H we + ~.ee emma ses o.HH n.m m.h m. m.mv mmma .uoo .mmoz omcmco o.nmflq omcmno nmuflmomoo omcmno cofluwa omcmno occmco mucooomflo once a ucoo pom pcmEoo ucoo Hod oum>flum ucoo mom Isouflu ucoo pom ofiooam pcoo you can mcmoq coflumooq I III I Juli.” ...I.. ,..I .II .IIIJUHIIII. IIIIIII. I II I II III-I Il "MIN I031." I I" I" I4. “I. ”4!“! N I": "III II.I I. NI”. IIIII .I. III II ....III:I.IIIII:I .vmmHImmmH o.m0umum woven: on» we xcmm pcooom ozu ppm .qu0 xuow 302 .mcHHOhoU Luuoz .tcmHmH ovens .mfl:m>a>mccom .muuomzcoommmf mo mxcmm .mofluflaflnoflq pco muommd uoflmfiII.m.m mqmwco ono>wom ammo: .omoHHoEmuv Hora OHOmom mOOHHm cwoumoz .mnuom .m mmeooe "condom wmv .wmm .hm.ma .aeau .aea .mum oco Hum hoarse raccoons co conch noooeaonmo .oaro noosaocH Q .umo> mop mo pmwflm orb Hoop How SH co>flm mpmom we mm we maI we omoumum oouflco mam mom mma mHH mma homo: mm MOH me me an umozsuoom on mm mm mm ov Oaucmaum nudom mm ma mm omI em oaucmapd OHS mm mm NH as mm ocoaesm 3oz w w w w w wwwmomoo cofluma mucsoomflo tam soap mufimomoo ISOHHU meoomm can msooq coflmom Imasoufiu n.5mmHImmma .coaoom mo mxcom opmuw mmwuflafiomflq one muommm HOmoz ca omcmru oompcOOHOAII.N.m momma 67 TABLE 3.3.--Percentage Change in Major Assets and Liabilities of Banks in Selected States and Cities 1834-1837. Circula- Location Loans and Specie Circu- Deposits tion and & Period Discounts lation DepOSltS % do % % % Maine Jan. 1835 Jan. 1837 77 177 36 113 53 Rhode Island Oct. 1834 March 1837 40 -48 49 -7 13 New York Statea Jan. 1835 Jan. 1837 48 58 52 57 54 Pennsylvaniab Nov. 1834 May 1837 64 -30 36 2 17 Virginia Jan. 1835 Jan. 1837 59 3O 56 71 65 Georgia Oct. 1834 April 1837 117 61 117 190 132 Ohio Jan. 1835 Jan. 1837 86 88 60 382 118 New York City Jan. 1835 Jan. 1837 51 7 94 28 48 New Orleans June 1835' Jan. 1837 58 10 55 62 59 aExcludes New York City banks. bExcludes Second Bank of the United States. Sources: Penn., Georgia, Maine, Virginia, R.I.: U.S. Congress, House, 26th Cong., 2nd Session, H.D. 111. New York State: U.S., Congress, House, Blst Cong., lst Session, H.E.D. 68, p. 372-3. Ohio: Berry, p. 588. New York City: N.Y.S. Assembly, Report Of Bank Commissioners, 58th Sess., Doc. 74, 60th Sess., Doc. 78. New Orleans: Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, Oct. 1842, p. 361. 68 New Orleans banks were managed conservatively in comparison with the state financed land banks of the region.48 There is also a difference between the performance of state banks in general and those which held government deposits. Within a few days of the announcement of the government's policy to use state banks as depositories for government funds, these banks were urged to use the newly gained funds to support an expansionary lending policy. A circular letter of the Treasury Department to the deposit banks on September 26, 1833, said, 'The deposits of public money will enable you to afford increased facilities to commerce and to extend your accommodations to individuals.‘ It also recommended, 'merchants engaged in foreign trade,‘ as the most deserving recipients of extended credit.49 The available data, found in Appendix Table B-4, support the hypothesis that deposit banks did expand their lending activities more than banks in general. Between January 1835 and November 1836, the loans and discounts of deposit banks increased by 143 per cent while note cir- culation rose by 168 per cent; in comparison, the average for all banks were 48 and 44 per cent respectively. In Chapter V we will examine the performance of deposit banks in more detail. The Federal government had an influence on the supply of money and credit that was more encompassing than its relations with the deposit banks. We shall conclude this chapter by looking more closely at how the monetary 69 and fiscal policies of the government influenced the supply of money and credit during the boom period of the mid-1830's. The Federal Government and the Supply of Money and Credit 1834-1835 At the same time the Federal government was encour- aging the expansion of the money supply, it was also attempt- ing to replace the existing paper money with hard money, specie and large denomination bank notes convertible into specie. The first major attempt to substitute specie for the existing money supply was the Coinage Act of 1834. The Act contributed to the massive specie inflows of 1834 but because the new mint ratio overvalued gold at the mint, It became impossible for the administration to substitute specie for notes of small denomination, for silver coins L . . were worth more in the bul- lion market than at the mint.50 In the next two years Congress and the Treasury department attempted to eliminate small denomination bank notes from the money supply and make the remaining bank notes completely convertible into specie. The executive and legislative branches of the Federal government followed the practices of the period and ignored the growing importance of demand deposits in the money supply. During 1835 and 1836, the Treasury department sent directives to the Treasury officials responsible for col- lecting and disbursing government funds, as well as to the 70 deposit banks. These directives were designed to remove smaller denomination bank notes from circulation and to make those notes which would thereafter circulate, converti- ble on demand into specie. On April 6, 1835, a Treasury circular informed all collecting and receiving officials that: (1) they could not receive bank notes in denomina- tion of less than five dollars starting after September 30, 1835, and that public Officials could not pay out such notes after May 1, 1836; (2) after July 4, 1836, the government would not accept or pay out notes of less than ten dollars; (3) the deposit banks were ordered to make one-fifth of every payment which did not exceed $500 in gold, if so required by the creditor; and (4) they were requested to cease issuing notes below the denomination of five dollars by July 4, 1836 and below ten dollars by March 3, 1837.51 On April 14, 1836, Congress passed an Act prohibit- ing the government from paying out notes of less than ten dollars and after March 1837, no notes of less than twenty dollars would be paid out. (Note that the previous Treasury circular of 1835 should have prevented this, starting in July.) It also sought to insure the complete converti— bility of all currency used by the government by ordering "that the United States government should not pay out any banknote of any denomination unless the same were payable on demand in gold or silver coin at the place where issued."52 Several states had already passed laws prohibiting the . I O 53 lssuance of notes of small denominatlons. 71 These laws, at both the state and federal level affected bank specie holdings, but not the supply of bank money. The banking system lost approximately six billion dollars in specie during 1835 and 1836. This loss of specie at a time when the United States was a net importer of specie and the high levels of coinage at the mind indicates that the public increased its demand for Specie. While the banks were losing specie to the public the supply of bank money rose by $76 million, again demonstrating the tenuous relationship between bank specie and bank money.54 The fiscal policy of the Federal government during these years had an important effect on the supply of money and the long-term capital markets, both domestic and foreign. Federal fiscal policies during this period centered on the problem of what to do with the mounting Federal surplus. This question occupied more and more of the attention of the executive and legislative branches when for all practi- cal purposes the national debt was eliminated by the end of 1834. The Federal government found itself running budgetary 55 The surpluses surpluses every year from 1830 to 1836. were the result of the economic prosperity of the period which led to rising imports and increasing custom's receipts. The Compromise Tariff Of 1833 lowered duties and receipts but land sales expanded tremendously in 1835 and 1836 resulting in the largest Federal surpluses prior to 1866. 72 Whether the surpluses would be inflationary or deflationary depended on what the government did with them. At first the surpluses were used to retire the Federal debt. The outstanding debt of the United States government at the end of 1830 was approximately $39 mil- lion. Between the end of that year and the end of 1832, the debt had been reduced by approximately $32 million, and by the end of 1834 it was less than $50,000. Repayment of the national debt affected not only the money supply but the supply of long-term credit as well. As the debt was reduced the supply of income earning assets available to investors decreased. This "closed an important field of conservative investment and returned funds to investors who then had to find other uses for them."56 Investors found these alternative sources of income earn- ing assets in state and private securities for internal improvements and banks, and in urban and rural real estate. The redemption of the national debt also built up the credit standing of American securities in England and on the Continent. Foreign investors believed that the Federal government would be ultimately responsible for the repayment of state debts as it did after the Revolutionary War. With the Federal debt eliminated it seemed to the foreign investors that the Federal government was in a better position to assume state debts if that eventuality arose. Finally the mere fact that a government had repaid 73 its debts impressed British investors who had been singed in the mid-1820's by South American bond issues. The net effect of debt retirement on the money supply appears to have been minimal. Repayment of domes- tically held debt involved a transfer of funds from those paying duties and purchasing bonds to those owning govern- ment securities. Repayment of the foreign held debt--approximately $13 million in 1830--entailed either the generation of an export surplus or refinancing with other types of debt instruments.58 If both of these did not supply the neces- sary foreign exchange earnings, the only remaining alterna- tive was the exportation of specie. From Appendix Table A-1, we see that there was a deficit in the balance of payments on current account for every year between 1831 and 1837. Only in 1831, however, was there a net specie out-flow, and Smith attributes this to the policies of the Second Bank of the United States and not to debt repayment.59 In 1832, when the national debt was reduced by $17 million, the London capital market eased. This enabled American state and local governments as well as some private corporations to float issues in London, thus supplying the foreign exchange needed to finance the repayment of the foreign held national debt as well as the deficit on cur- rent account.60 The repayment of the foreign held national debt was generally accomplished by refinancing with other securities. 74 After the Federal debt had been largely paid off, the continuing Federal surpluses were deposited in various selected state banks. We have already seen that these deposit banks did pursue a more expansionary lending policy than banks in general. In Chapter V we will more closely examine the relationship between the Federal surpluses in 1835 and 1836 and the growth of the money supply. The expansion of bank money, the major component of the money supply, was due not primarily to specie flows but the response Of banks to the credit needs of a growing economy. The Federal government contributed to this expan- sion by shifting deposits from the S.B.U.S. to deposit banks. It also, however, increased uncertainty about the stability Of the money supply by not rechartering the S.B.U.S. and by its actions concerning the type of notes which it would accept. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER III lEli Shapiro, Ezra Solomon and William L. White, Money and Banking, Fifth Edition (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1968), p. 52. 2Stuart Bruchey, Cotton and the Growth of the American Economy: 1790-1860 (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, Inc., 1967), pp. 225, 231. 3Shapiro, Solomon and White, p. 53. 4Bruchey, p. 246. 5Norman Buck, The Develgpment of the Organization of Anglo-American Trade, 1800-1850 (New Haven: Yale Uni- versity Press, 1925), p. 160. Paul F. McGouldrick, New England Textiles in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridg5?— Harvard University Press, 1968), p. 42. 6Bruchey, p. 224. 7Joseph E. Hedges, Commercial Banking and the Stock Market Before 1863 (The John Hopkins University Studies in Historical and Political Science Series, Vol LVI, No. 1, .Baltimore: The John Hopkins University Press, 1938), p. 65. 8Buck, p. 82. An examination of the Bostwick papers excerpted in Bruchey shows that for interstate transactions, Bostwick made payment with checks. For intrastate settlements, Bostwick also used drafts. Bruchey, IHP- 247-249, 252, 254, 255, 258, 263. 9North, Economic Growth, Table A-VIII, p. 233. 10See Stuart Bruchey, pp. 222-225. 11Matthew B. Hammond, "The Cotton Industry" American Ekxnumnic Association Publication, New Series #1 (New York: McMillijuh 1897), p. 71. For a discussion of the relation- ship between state banking in Louisiana and the cotton industry see Stephen A. Caldwell, A Banking History of Louisiana (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1935) . p~ 54- 75 76 12Bruchey, pp. 222, 227. l3Buck, pp. 82, 86. l4Bruchey, p. 229. 15Buck, p. 87. 16Buck, p. 55. 17Buck, p. 87. 18Buck, pp. 154-155. 19Buck, p. 157. Arthur H. Cole, "Evolution of the Foreign Exchange Market of the United States," Journal of Economic and Business History, Vol. 1, No. 3 (May, 1929), p. 402. 20See Appendix Table B-5. ZlBuck, p. 158; Smith, pp. 89, 142. 22Cole, Journal of Economic and Business History, Vol. L, p. 399. 23 See Appendix Table A-1. 24Temin, pp. 82-83. 25Lead-lag relationships between changes in the money supply and changes in aggregate indices such as GNP or the C.P.I. are not sufficient to determine causal rela- tionships. See comment of James Tobin in Controllipg Monetary Aggregates (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September, 1969), p. 22. 26 Temin, p. 80. 27Losses to the Continent were $12 million, those to Asia $7 million. See Temin, p. 81. 28Temin, p. 81. 29Temin erroneously listed $4.65 as the gold par. Temin, p. 65. 30Temin, p. 66. A five per cent premium on silver meant a London price ratio of 15.7:1. 77 31According to the Financial Register, the silver par was eight per cent while a House report listed it as ranging between seven and eight per cent. See Financial Register, Vol. 1, p. 79, and source cited for Appendix Table B-lO, p. 656. 32Margaret G. Myers, The New York Mongy Market, Vol. 1 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1939), p. 74. 33Paul T. Ellsworth, and J. Clark Leith, The Inter- national Economy, Fourth Edition (New York: The Macmillan CO., 1969), pp. 343-344. Autonomous transactions are those undertaken for their own account and not to settle payment imbalances. 34 Temin, p. 64. 35Smith, pp. 30, 175. 36These estimates are derived by subtracting estimated bank specie holdings from the estimated total specie supply. The specie series used are those of the Comptroller. Using an alternative series constructed by Temin the comparable figures are 15.2 per cent and 21.2 per cent. See Temin, pp. 184, 189-190 for a discussion of these two specie series. 37A deposit resulting from the lodgement Of currency or its equivalent is called a primary deposit. A deposit arising from the exchange of a bank debt for the debt of others is called a derivative deposit. Eli Shapiro, Ezra Solomon and William L. White, Money and Banking, Fifth Edition (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1968), pp. 124-125. 38 Hammond, pp. 188, 558. 39Hammond, p. 688. 40Hammond, pp. 188-189, 688, 690. 41Hammond, pp. 131-137, 696-697. 42Hammond, p. 695. 43We will see in Chapter V that Section 8 of the Deposit Act gave the Secretary of the Treasury the power to fix what amounted to reserve ratios for the deposit banks. 44Temin, pp. 77-78. 78 45Kane, pp. 44, 46, 359-360; and Robert Ferber and P. J. Verdoorn, Research Methods in Economics and Business (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1962), pp. 336-337, 384-386. 46R2, the coefficient of determination, shows the percentage of variation in the dependent variables (that on the left-hand side of the regression equation), which is explained by variations in the independent variable (those on the right-hand side of the equation). The number in brackets under the regression coefficient is the Standard Error of the Estimate. This is a means of estimating the probability that a particular regression coefficient was produced from a population where the observed relationship is nonexistent. If we used, as in these two equations, annual data for 16 years, and if the regression coefficient is at least 2.145 times its standard error of the estimate, then the regression coefficient would be expected to occur five times out of 100 purely as a result of chance. D.W. is the Durbin-Watson statistic which measures the possible existence of auto-correlation, that is the extent to which a variable has been omitted or that there is a correlation of the various time series with themselves; i.e., the dif- ferent values of the variable are related over time. Where the D.W. statistic is given, this indicates that the hypo- thesis of the existence of autocorrelation has been rejected at the five per cent significance level. In economics, the existence of auto correlation means that we accept more frequently than we should the statistical significance of the regression coefficient. Kane, pp. 360-361, 368; Ferber and Verdoorn, pp. 87, 95-97. 47 See Smith, PP. 226-227. 48We will see in the next Chapter that most of the outstanding debts incurred by the states in this region were for the formation of banks set up to facilitate the growing and sale of cotton. 49David Kinley, The Independent Treasury of the United States and Its Relations to the Banking of the Country (Washington: National Monetary Commission, 1910), p. 29. Also see Harry N. Scheiber, "The Pet Banks in Jacksonian Politics and Finance, 1833-1841," Journal of Economic History, Vol. 23, No. 2 (June, 1963): P. 199. 50Paul Studenski and Herman E. Krooss, Financial History of the United States, Second Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1963), p. 109. See also Schlesinger, pp. 126-127. 79 51Kinley, p. 31; Niles, April 11, 1835, p. 92; and March 5, 1836, p. 11. 52Dewey, p. 228. 53Schlesinger, p. 128. 54Appendix Table, B-2, B-7. 55See Appendix Table A-2. 56Hammond, p. 454. Also see Albert Gallatin, Suggestions on the Banks and Currency of the Several States (New York: Wiley and Putnam, 1841), pp. 32-33. 57Edward G. Bourne, The History of the Surplus Revenue of 1837 (New York: G. P. Putnam's, 1885), p. 14. 58Paul B. Trescott, "The United States Government and National Income, 1790-1860," Trands in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 24 (Princeton: Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960): p. 352. 59 Smith, p. 92. 60See Appendix Table A-2 and Smith, p. 158. APPENDIX TO CHAPTER III The following regression equations represent an attempt to use the available information to determine the importance of British credit to the Anglo-American trade. As already mentioned in Chapter III, the value of inland bills of exchange was used to indicate conditions in the British credit market. Both the original data and first differences were used. It should be noted that although an R2 of .67 was obtained for the relationship between exports of United Kingdom textiles and inland bills of exchange, the use of first differences reduced the R2 to .259. Equations were run in the form of Y = f (X) and X = f (Y). The coefficient of determination, R2 is the same for both, but by looking at the regression coeffi- cients we may obtain more insight into the causal relation- ships.1 I. United Kingdom Export of Cotton Textiles (Y1) and Inland Bills of Exchange, (X1). First differences are Y2 and X2 respectively. Y1 = 62.8 + .64 x1 R2 = .67* (.120) DW = 1.108** Y2 = 2.12 + .425 x2 R2 = .259* (.20) DW = 2.405* 1Kane, pp. 242-244. 80 81 x1 = 15.1 + 1.05 Y1 R = .67** (.195) DW = 1.05 x2 = 2.906 + .609 Y2 R2 = .259* (.286) 0w = 1.69 II. United States Imports From Great Britain (Y3 ) and Inland Bills of Exchange. First Differences and Y and X 4 2' Y3 = — .043 + .1716 X1 R2 = .175** (.099) DW = 1.509* Y4 = - 4.2 + .306 x2 R2 = .139** (.212) DW = 1.694* x1 = 203.6 + 1.02 Y3 R2 = .175** (.59) DW = .3122** x2 = 6.78 + .453 Y4 R2 = .139** (.313) DW = 1.493* III. United States Cotton Exports to the United Kingdon (YS ) and Inland Bills of Exchange. First Differences are Y and X 6 2' Y5 = -97.21 + 1.86 x1 R2 = .27* (.816) DW = .855** y6 = 32.14 - .777 x2 R2 = .045** (.992) DW = 3.216** x1 = 194.4 + .145 Y5 R2 = .27* (.064) DW = .816** x2 = 7.28 - .058 Y6 R2 = .045** (.074) 0w = 1.538* Sources: United Kingdom Exports of Cotton Textiles and United States Cotton Exports to the United Kingdon: Appendix Table C-3. United Kingdom Bills of Exchange: Appendix Table B~50 82 United States Imports From Great Britain: The Statistical History of the United States, Series U. 142, p. 553. CHAPTER IV THE GROWTH OF AGGREGATE DEMAND IN THE MID-1830's The banking system was willing and it appeared able to meet the growing demands placed on it during the mid- 1830's for money and credit. In this chapter we will examine those factors which generated this demand. Aggregate demand in the United States grew as a result of the process of expanding economic specialization which meant a widening of the market nexus thus further increasing the demand for money and credit. Economic specialization and its concommitant, increasing economic efficiency was stimulated primarily by four forces during this period: 1. expanding cotton production in the South; 2. the settlement of new grain lands and cities in the mid-west; 3. the growth of manufacturing and urban centers in New England and the mid-Atlantic states; 4. the expanding network of roads, canals and railroads, often financed by state and local governments, which connected the growing sections of the nation. 83 84 Which of these were of paramount importance is dif- ficult to say. Before proceeding to examine these factors we will look at one hypothesis dealing with this question. D.C. North in his "Economic Growth of the United States," wrote that, Cotton was strategic because it was the major independent variable in the interdependent structure of internal and international trade. The demand for western foodstuffs and northeastern services and manufactures were basically dependent upon the income received from the cotton trade. . . . The cotton trade was the immediate impetus for . . . regional speciali- zation, and the growth of cotton incomes in the 1830's was the most important proximate influence upon the spurt of manufacturing growth of that decade. In a more recent work, "Growth and Welfare in the American Past," North appears to have modified his hypo— thesis. In answering the question of what factors brought about the growth of the American economy during the ante- bellum period he concluded that, We must first observe that industrialization in the northeast, though important, cannot claim full credit. . . . It is clear that all three major regions contributed. In both the West and the South, incomes rose with more efficient agriculture and with migration into new and richer lands. . . . It was the whole American economy that was responsible for the accelerated growth.2 This does not mean that North still does not believe that cotton was important, for a few pages prior to the above statement he wrote that, Cotton made the big difference in the economy after 1815, ruling as king in the South and exerting an important influence in the national pattern of development.3 85 From these two comments we might conclude that cotton was important, that without the growth in the cotton market in the mid-1830's the growth of the American economy might have been less than it was.4 Cotton and the American Economy in the Mid-1830's Our interest in the cotton market lies in its rela- tion to the boom of the mid—1830's and the panics and deflation of the late 1830's and early 1840's. In this chapter we will concentrate on the former period, later chapters will cover the latter. What factors contributed to the rise in cotton prices during 1834-1836? What effect did the growth of the cotton market have on the American economy in general? These are the questions which will concern us in the next few pages. The main purchaser of American cotton was Great Britain and it was the economic health of that country that determined the course of the American cotton industry.5 The grain harvests in Great Britain were crucial in this respect. During the mid-1830's the British grain crops were good and this stimulated the demand for American cotton. Good harvests by lowering grain prices increased the real income of British consumers and thus increased the demand for British textiles. 86 The primary cause of the rise in the price of cotton in the years prior to 1836 was the rise in demand in Britain deriving from a series of good har— vests. Not all British cotton goods were consumed at home, and there were presumably other factors influ- encing the demand for cotton, but the rise in the home demand was the most systematic inflationary factor.6 Indirectly, good grain harvests, through their effect on the money markets of Great Britain increased the demand for British textiles and thus for raw cotton. Good harvests meant that little specie had to be exported to purchase grains. This facilitated the easy money policies pursued by the Bank of England during these years. It was easier for British textile exporters to obtain credit just as it was easier for the manufacturers to obtain credit to purchase raw cotton. The health of the American cotton industry depended on conditiOns in the grain fields and money markets of Great Britain. In 1837 and 1839 we will see the vital :hmportance of these factors to the American cotton industry and.the American economy in general. The importance of cotton to the American economy, ausiNorth indicated, lay in the income its production and salxa generated for the American economy as a whole. Cotton ale“) contributed to the growth of the American economy thrtNJgh its role as the main source of foreign exchange earTuings during these years. Finally, there is also the liklihood that rising cotton prices contributed to the inflow of British capital, especially to the Southern states. 87 Cotton gave the planters the purchasing power to buy domestic and imported manufactured goods and foodstuffs from the mid-Western states. Northern merchants, concen- trated in New York supplied the South with much of the manufactured goods it purchased. This demand for manu- factured goods stimulated production and income in the East thus contributing to the East's increasing specialization and urbanization. They also supplied the shipping and ancillary services needed to ship the raw cotton from the South to the textile mills of New England and Europe as well as the reverse trade in manufactured goods. Though much has been written in recent years to cast doubts on the assumption that the mid-West was an important supplier of foodstuffs to the South, little in these works had dealt specifically with the New South.8 Yet it was in the New South, those states bordering on the Gulf Coast and the Mississippi river, that we had the most :napid growth in population during the 1830's. Moreover, Soy 1833 this region supplied about 52 per cent of the total cxrtton produced in the United States and the average for ‘the 1834-1837 period was about 59 per cent.9 The New South might have been a food deficit region of some magnitude given its population growth. Where could thij; food have come from? One cannot simply assume that time food came from the surplus regions of the Old South. 11:1may have been more expensive to ship food from the 88 interior of the Old South lying east of the Alleghenies than to ship it down the Ohio and Mississippi river system or across the Erie Canal and down the coast. We do not know how much of the produce of the mid-West shipped down the Ohio-Mississippi system never reached New Orleans, but was consumed by plantations along the river valley. Finally we do not know how much of what was shipped from New Orleans went to ports along the Gulf Coast.10 Until much more is known about the production of foodstuffs, and the coastal and inland trade of the New South, we cannot reject the hypothesis that it was an important market for the produce of the mid—West during the 1830's. Besides generating incomes outside the South as well as within it, cotton was important because it was the main source of exchange earnings for the United States in these years. Exports of cotton accounted for about 36 per cent of total United States exports in 1833; in the next three years it accounted for 49 per cent, 65 per cent and 71 per cent, respectively, of total United States exports. Tflue bills of exchange arising from the export of cotton lualped to pay for expanding United States imports as well an; to meet some of the needs for repaying short—term debts auui the interest on the long-term debt. We will see in laixar chapters that fluctuations in cotton export earnings had serious consequences for the foreign exchange markets and the Eastern banks in 1837 and 1839. ll 89 The booming cotton market also helped the sale of American securities in Great Britain and the Continent. Rising cotton prices and the continuing flow of cotton bills increased the confidence of foreign investors to American securities. This was especially true for the securities issued by the states of the New South. The proceeds of the securities sold by these latter states were mainly used to set up banks to finance the expansion of cotton growing and marketing.12 By purchasing these securities British investors might have been conscious of the aid they were giving to their textile industry, but we have no information to indicate that this was so. Cotton was important to the boom of the mid-1830's. It provided the main source of foreign exchange earnings during the period and contributed to the climate which induced foreign investment in the United States. As we Inated in the beginning of this chapter, cotton was impor- tant.in stimulating regional specialization, but we do ruyt know how important. Finally we do not know when the pnnocess of regional specialization and increasing economic effiiciency became independent of cotton, if it did, during the 1830 ' s. Specialization, Urbanization and Growth in the Mid—West and East The Mid-West During the 1830's the mid-West was the most rapidly growing region in the nation. Except for the New South, 90 its population growth of 108 per cent was more than twice that of any other region of the United States.13 The growth of the mid-West was facilitated by an expanding transporta— tion system which aided the flow of settlers into the region and the outflow of its produce. The demand for the produce of the mid-West grew rapidly during this period. Expanding pOpulation, both in farm areas and urban centers provided a growing intraregional demand which was increased by interregional demand. With expanding markets there was expanding specialization which meant in turn more urban centers to meet the needs of the farmers. It was during the 1830's that cities such as Chicago, Cleveland and Detroit grew from towns of less than 2,500 inhabitants to small cities of 4,500, 6,100, and 9,100 respectively. A vital factor contributing to the growth of urban centers was access to river, lake or canal trans— ;mortation. The population of Lexington, Kentucky grew by cnily'l7 per cent during the decade while that of Louisville, cums hundred miles to the West on the Ohio River grew by 106 per cent. 14 How much of the growth in pOpulation in both agri— culinaral and more urban regions of the mid-West, took place durdJng the early and mid-1830's is unknown. The population figures are for census years and we have to rely on more 9l indirect information if we are to shed some light on the time pattern of this growth. We do have some information on Chicago which indicates that most of the growth took place prior to the last years of the decade, but we have no basis to generalize from this information. We have previously seen that the population of Chicago grew from less than 2,500 in 1830 to 4,470 in 1840. According to the Report of the City Controller of Chicago for 1887, the pOpulation of that city was 4,170 in 1837.15 Thus between 1830 and 1837, most of the decade increase in Chicago's population took place. F. Cyril James, in his history of banking in Chicago wrote that, The total value, at the prices then current, of the land in the present city limits of Chicago had reached a figure of $10,500,000, an amount 60 times as great as its total value in 1830.16 Public land sales in the mid-West reached an ante- bellum peak in 1836, having increased by 685 per cent between 1833 and 1837.17 How much of this increase re- flected increased population is unknown. Moreover, public land sales in the 1837-1839 period were above the levels of 1830-1833 so that there may have been significant popula- tion increases during these latter years as well. The population of the mid-West grew rapidly during the 1830's, and it is possible that much of this increase 'took place during the early and mid-1830's. Most likely 92 the rate of population increase declined in the last three years of the 1830's. The problem of insufficient data confronts us again when we look at the growth of agricultural output in the mid-West during the 1830's. Much of the regions output never reached the market place in that it was consumed by the producers. Another substantial portion was consumed by the inhabitants of the growing towns and cities of the mid-West. What information we do have, deals with inter- regional flows and perhaps reflects only a small portion of the growth in output that did take place. Interregional shipping data show a rapid expansion of trade but one must be careful in their use. Receipts on all Ohio canals, for example, rose by 330 per cent be- tween 1830 and 1836, but we do not know how much of this increase was due to the opening of new canals or the exten- sion of existing ones. Between 1834 and 1836, the increase was 40 per cent, perhaps this is a more accurate indicator of the growth in output.18 Of course we still do not know what proportion of these receipts arose from the shipments of goods from the East. From fiscal 1830 through fiscal 1836, the value of receipts of produce from the interior at New Orleans rose by 77 per cent, but we do not know the origins or composi— tion of the shipments. Furthermore, we do not know how Inuch of the shipments down the Ohio—Mississippi system was l l 93 purchased before reaching New Orleans. The tonnage of vessels employed on the western rivers increased by slightly over 142 per cent between 1830 and 1836.19 Information on East-West trade is even scanter. Estimates of Eastbound shipments via the Erie Canal did not commence until 1836. The tonnage of vessels registered at all ports on the Great Lakes and the Saint Lawrence River increased by almost 329 per cent between 1830 and 1836 with 69 per cent of the increase taking place in the 1833-1836 period. In comparison, only 28 per cent of the increase of tonnage on Western rivers took place during the same period.20 The volume of trade between the mid-West and other sections of the nation increased greatly during the early and mid-1830's. This reflected increasing production and income. In turn this meant an expanding market for eastern manufacturers and merchants. Expansion in the East Growth in the mid-Atlantic states and New England in the early and mid-1830's arose from increasing special- ization of trade and manufacturing and from increasing ‘urbanization. The demand factors giving rise to this came from the expanding markets of the South and mid-West as (Hell as from the growing commercial and manufacturing centers of the East itself. 94 Industrial output grew during the early and mid— 1830's, but not enough to match the growth in demand. The estimated output of the New England textile industry rose by 200 per cent between 1830 and 1836. Surprisingly, how- ever, only 40 per cent of this increase came during the boom years of 1834-1836.21 Iron production increased by 65 per cent during the 1830-1836 period with half of this coming in the 1834-1836 period.22 Total anthracite coal production increased by 290 per cent during the 1830-1836 period, but again only about 38 per cent of this increase coming in the 1834-1836 period.23 The pattern of growth in industrial output during the boom years is one of the reasons for the rapid rise in prices and increasing imports during this period. Domestic production could not keep pace with the growth in demand. Mercantile trade expanded greatly during these years. More and more goods flowed through the Eastern ports destined for the markets of the interior and the South. This trade generated income and employment in the Eastern seaports as well as the interior distribution centers which were part of the channel of trade from the factories of Great Britain and New England to the farmers and planters of America. Paramount among the mercantile centers was New York. It was the entreport for the cotton trade and the growing markets of the interior which was opened up to the city by 95 the Erie Canal. While total United States imports rose 75 per cent during the 1833-1836 period, imports into the port of New York rose by 110 per cent. New York's share of total imports rose from 54 per cent to 65 per cent during the same period.24 The increase in trade was reflected in the burgeon- ing population and wealth of New York City. New York, thanks in considerable degree to the rapid expansion of its suburb, Brooklyn, the increase in trade following the completion of the Erie Canal, and its growing dominance of the import trade, grew most rapidly of the Four Great Eastern Seaports and contributed the largest share, especially in the 1830's, to the country's urbanization.25 The city's population increased by 62 per cent during the decade while that of Boston, Philadelphia, and Baltimore rose by 38 per cent, 37 per cent, and 26 per cent respec- tively.26 The wealth of the city also grew rapidly but there is a problem in using this information. A great fire in the city in December 1835 led to a large increase in the number of buildings constructed in 1836 at the then higher prices. The number of buildings erected in New York City rose from 877 in 1834 to 1,259 in 1835 and to 1,826 in 27 1836. The assessed value of real property in the city rose by 140 per cent in the 1830-1836 period with 88 per cent of this increase in the 1834-1836 period. The asses- sed value of personal property rose by 81 per cent, with 28 69 per cent of this being in the 1834-1836 period. The 96 growth of New York City reflected the importance of urbaniza- tion to the growth of the American economy during the 1830's. Urbanization in the East depended on the expanding market economy and access to the growing transportation system. In New York State, the Erie Canal was a major agent of urbanization, and not just for New York City. During the first ten years of the canal's operation, house- hold textile manufactures in New York State fell by about 47 per cent, on a per capita basis it was 55 per cent.29 As one travels westward along the canal, the rate of urban- ization of cities along the canal increased. During the 1830's, the population of Albany increased by 39 per cent while that of Troy, Schenectady, Utica, Rochester and Buffalo increased by 66 per cent, 58 per cent, 54 per cent 119 per cent and 109 per cent respectively. For New York State as a whole, population increased by 27 per cent.30 In New England, mill towns were also growing. The pOpulation of Fall River, Lowell and Lynn increased by 60 per cent, 220 per cent, and 54 per cent respectively while that of Massachusetts rose by 21 per cent during the decade. In Maine, the boom in lumber, deriving from expanded urban construction and shipbuilding, was reflected in the growth of cities such as Augusta on the Kennebec River and Bangor on the Penobscot. Both cities grew from less than 2,500 in 1830 to 5,300 and 8,600 respectively by the end of the decade.31 97 Urbanization was a two—sided process. The expansion of the cotton industry in the South and the settlement of new grain lands and the beginning of new urban centers in the mid-West stimulated the growth of urban centers in the East. Urbanization itself further increased the need for economic specialization not only in the growing mercantile and manufacturing centers in the East but also in the regions which supplied these centers with raw materials and foodstuffs. A common thread throughout our discussion of the economies of the South, mid-West and East was the increased economic specialization. Demand factors, especially in the South and mid-West were important in bringing about this specialization but the everwidening transportation net furnished the underpinning for it. The expansion of this infrastructure continued throughout the decade with the peak in both canal and railroad construction being reached in the last years of the decade and the first of the next. It now remains for us to determine the extent of this con- struction during the mid-1830's and the role of the state governments in financing it. State Governments and the Growth of Transportation Infrastructure State governments played an important role in the financing of internal improvements during this decade. Aid was extended in the form of bond issues to finance public 98 or semi-public projects, land grants, tax remissions, granting of banking privileges and the purchase of pri- vately issued bonds.32 In Table 4.1 we have the percentage distribution of state debts by purposes for which they were originally contracted. Canals, railroads and turnpikes accounted for 68 per cent ($109.7 million) of the debts outstanding in 1838. Note that in every state outside of the New South, excluding Maine, the majority of the debt incurred was for internal improvements. In the New South banking was the main purpose for which state debts were incurred. There is little information available on the extent of canal and railroad mileage built during the 1830's. According to Taylor, about 2,000 miles of new canals were constructed in the 1830's, the total mileage increased by 165 per cent during the decade. Estimates of railroad construction vary greatly and are believed not to be relia- ble for measuring annual changes. There are two estimates of railroad mileage during the 1830's, those of Poor and Shuman, the former showing an increase of 2,279 miles while the latter estimates the increase as being 2,225 during the 1830's.33 The internal improvements of the 1830's depended on the availability of long-term credit, especially British, and on domestic banking facilities.34 We will see in later chapters that the monetary panic of 1837 did not seriously 99 TABLE 4.l.--Per Cent Distribution of State Debts Outstanding In 1838 By Purposes For Which Incurred.a State Banking Canals Railroads Turnpikes Misc. Alabama 72 0 28 Arkansas 100 0 0 0 Illinois 26 08 64 0 02 Indiana 12 57 22 10 0 Kentucky 27 35 35 05 32 Louisiana 97 002 02 0 01 Maine 0 0 0 0 100 Maryland 0 49 48 0 2 Massachusetts 0 0 100 0 0 Michigan 0 47 49 0 04 Mississippi 100 0 0 Missouri 100 0 0 New York 0* 73 21 0 06 Ohio 0 100 0 0 0 Pennsylvania 0 61 18 09 11 So. Carolina 0 27 35 0 38 Tennessee 42 004 52 02 0 Virginia 0 57 32 05 05 TOTAL 31 35 25 05 05 aWill not necessarily equal 100% because of rounding. Source: United States, Bureau of the Census, Tenth Census of the United States, 1880, Report on Valuation, Taxation, and Public Indebtedness in the United States, Vol. 7, pp. 526-554. 100 disturb the inflow of long-term capital, thus states and private corporations were able to continue these projects. The collapse of the Anglo-American trade structure in 1839 signaled an end to these capital imports. The disorgan- ization of domestic banking with its widespread suspensions and failures made it difficult for these projects to utilize the funds they had in banks. When the funds already in the pipelines were used up, the projects gener- ally ground to a halt. The decline in construction coming at a time when other sectors of the economy were already facing falling demand conditions contributed to the severi- ty of the deflation which lasted until 1844. The existance of many unfinished projects and defaulted bond issues made recovery that much more difficult. Access to foreign capital markets and dependence on domestic banks perhaps led to excess construction in the 1830's and to the in- ability to revive construction, especially in the west, during the 1840's. Various policies were implemented by states to induce banks to work with their internal improvement pro- jects. When extensive new canal construction was under- taken in Ohio in 1836, the Commercial Bank (of Lake Erie) was named as a disbursing agent . . . the state Treasurer c00perated by receiving the bank's own notes in receipt to takes, agreeing to 'give them such direction in small lots as would prevent their early return' for redemption.35 After the monetary panic of 1837, some banks found themselves required to underwrite bond issues and sometimes they became lOl lenders of last resort to the state. These practices also occurred before 1837, the most notable example being the chartering of the United States Bank of Pennsylvania in 1836.36 State financing of internal improvements tended to be inflationary. At the full-employment situation existing in the mid-1830's, debt financing could only be non- inflationary if: 1. It resulted in no new money creation or any increase in the velocity of circulation of money, and if, 2. Bond purchasers curtailed their consumption by the amount of the bonds and the resources so released were transferred to the issuers of the bonds. These non-inflationary conditions were not fulfilled. The sale of bonds to banks and foreigners normally meant an increase in the money supply. Furthermore, it is highly unlikely that non-bank bond purchasers in the United States curtailed their consumption by a parallel amount. We saw that the retirement of the federal debt released funds which flowed into alternative investments such as state bonds issued to finance canals and railroads. Such purchases were done not out of current income but from an alteration in individuals wealth. Debt financing of canals and rail- roads were inflationary in the 1830's. They resulted in increases in the supply of money without any significant transfer of resources. 102 Let us look a bit more closely at the inflationary effects of investments in internal improvements. First we must look at the composition of this investment. In the 1830's the emphasis in internal improvements shifted from canals to railroads. Perhaps most of the routes suitable for canals were already developed or in the process of so being. During the boom years of the mid-1830's there was a slight decline in canal investment while that on rail- roads rose significantly. For the decade as a whole, rail- road investment rose by 1,000 per cent while that for canals rose by 91 per cent. By the end of the decade investments in railroads exceeded those on canals whereas in 1830 they were only about 21 per cent of canal investment.37 Investment in internal improvement projects generated income in the areas where the construction was taking place and in the domestic capital goods industries supplying equip- ment for the construction of the project and its rolling stock. If we assume that a dollar Spent on capital goods had a greater multiplier-accelerator effect on the economy than a dollar spent on construction labor, then the shifting of funds from canals to railroads might have intensified the inflationary pressures during the mid-1830's. The shift to railroad con- struction also intensified the balance of payments problem as almost all of the iron imports during the 1830's consisted of 38 rolled iron used as rails. Finally, if workers were attracted away from agriculture into the construction of these 103 projects this might have led to a less rapid growth of agri- cultural output increasing the prices of foodstuffs. So far we have examined the magnitude and possible inflationary effects of internal improvement investments during the 1830's. Countering these inflationary pressures were the increased economic specialization and economic efficiency resulting from reduced transportation costs and widening markets. It appears though, that the net effect of these investments was to intensify the inflationary pressures in the early and mid-1830's. Aggregate demand expanded in the mid-1830's pri- marily because of the growing demand for Southern cotton and the settlement of the mid—West. This induced growth in the East as mercantile trade and manufacturing indus- tries responded to the demand eminating from the interior and the South. Urbanization in the East as well as in the mid-West also contributed to the process of specialization and growth. The building of the transportation infra- structure quickened specialization and urbanization while contributing to the growth in demand. The picture of the American economy we have examined in this chapter is one of prosperity, as can be seen in Table 4.2. Yet as early as the spring of 1835 we begin to find some uneasiness in the press. In May, 1835 Niles' National Register carried the following editorial statement, “We shall offer a selection of articles as to what is going 104 xflpammmm .pmuwu mousom NH 30m .mwmwamm .aa .xmmma ..oaH .mpmtmaanam pHmmmuwmm .« mmflumm .mno manna .ma n mmaumm..am~ .m ammx .omx mmaumm “QGOUV ucmmmnm 05¢ ou mmEflB HmwcoHou Scum mmumuw pmuHCD 0:» mo muoumflm Havapmflumum one .H .m .5 atom .pm .Ha .ma .immmfl ..oaH ..oo 4 coupoz .z.z .xnoa 3621 N56: loom QmeOmMUMh one smegma umumm w .gm .Appma ..o:H ..oo 8 couuoz .3.3 woven: 0:“ mo nuzouw OHEocoom .emm .mmm .mmm .mvm .oNH “xnow 302v ommanomna .mmpmum 0:9 .guuoz .O mmmamsoo ma .oaum .wla mBOm "mmouoom mHanHm>m uoc u .m.: .Hmmm cowpospoum mmmalvmma ca mownm xmmmm vv ova mpnomxm copuou mm Hm mAmcmmHHo 302V mmownm coppoo omm omm Ammmmuoauamom flame [Ill .mmmalomma mmenmm anocoom pmuomamm ca mmmcmno mmMpcmouomuu.m.v mamas 105 on in the way of speculation. Verily, the people are mad!"39 The pro-Jackson New York Evening Post, blaming the banks, warned the New York business community about the eventual outcome of the speculation taking place. We believe that the community intoxicated with the favors of the banks, as with a cup of a modern Circe, have lost sight of providence, and are blindly rushing into a state of things from which they will not be easily retrived. A crisis is approaching, and it is near at hand, to which the panic and pres- sure of last year (1834) will be a trifling in com- parison. In the last four months of the year a much more ominous development took place. The Baring Brothers, one of the leading firms in the Anglo-American trade, began to curtail their Operations. "The basic assumption was that prices of merchandise and securities were so high that reaction was inevitable."41 The growth of the Southern cotton industry, the construction of canals and railroads and the trade in im- ported goods depended on the health of two foreign markets, the British cotton and money markets. It would be in these Imarkets that the difficulties of the late 1830's and early £1840's had their roots. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER IV lNorth, Economic Growth of the United States, pp. 67, 167. 2North, Growth and Welfare in the American Past, p. 84. 3North, p. 76. 4For a discussion on the effects of cotton and slavery on American economic development and growth see Alfred H. Conrad, et. al., "Slavery as an Obstacle to Economic Growth in the United States: A Panel Discus- sion." The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 27, No. 4 (December 1967). The readers attention is also called to footnote eight of this chapter. 5Peter Temin, "The Causes of Cotton-Price Fluctua- tions in the 1830's," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XLIX (November, 1967). 6Temin, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XLIX, p. 470. 7Stuart Bruchey, Cotton and the Growth of the .American Economy: 1790-1860 (New York: Harcourt, Brace auni World, Inc., 1967), p. 226. For a discussion of some (If the Southern attempts to bypass the Northern merchants .and shippers see Herbert Wender, "Southern Commercial Con- \nmntions, 1837-1859," John Hopkins University Studies in Histcmical and Political Science, Series XLVIII, No. 4, 1930. 8For an example of the difficulties involved in measniring the trade of the mid—West with the South see Allxart Fishlow, "Ante-bellum Interregional Trade Recon- sitkared," Postscript on Antebellum Interregional Trade," and Robert W. Fogel, "A Provisional View of the 'New Ecommnnic History,'" "American Interregional Trade in the l9tJIICentury," in Ralph Andreano, ed., New Views on American Exmuumnic Development (Cambridge: Schenkman Publishing Co., Inc., 1965). 107 9The population of the New South rose from 727,000 in 1830 to 1,471,000 by 1840, a 102 per cent increase.. The comparable figures for the entire South are 3,774,405 in 1830 and 4,749,875 in 1840, a 26 per cent increase. See North, Economic Growth of the United States, p. 257, and Statistical History of the United States, p. 13, Series A-123-180. Cotton production data from The Commercial Review of the South and West, Vol. 4, No. 1, September 1847, p. 86. 10The population of Natchez rose from less than 2,500 to 4,200 during the 1830's. Mobile's pOpulation rose from 3,194 to 12,672 in the same period. George R. Taylor, "American Urban Growth Preceding the Railway Age," The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 27, No.-3 (SeptembEE, 1967). p. 315. 11North, Economic Growth of the United States, p. 233. 12North, p. 195. 13Statistical History of the United States, p. 13, Series A-123-180. 14Taylor, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 27, pp. 315, 338. 15Richard T. Ely, Taxation in American States and Cities (New York: 1888), p. 488. 16F. Cyril James, The Growth of Chicago Banks: The .Formative Years, 1816-1896, 2 Vol. (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1938), I, p. 103. 17North, Economic Growth of the United States, p. 256. 18North, p. 250. 19North. pp. 250—252. 2oNorth, p. 250. 21Lance E. Davis and Louis H. Stettler III, "The NemriEngland Textile Industry, 1825-1860: Trends and leurtuations," Output, Employment and Productivity in the:t1nited States After 1800 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 30, Imational Bureau of Economic Research, 1966), p. 221. 108 2Taussig, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 11, p. 379. 23Hunt's Merchants Magazine, Vol. 8, December, 1842, p. 458. . 24Appendix Table A—1 and Table 9.2. 336 25Taylor, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 27, p. . 26Taylor, p. 311. 27Niles' National Register, May 11, 1840, p. 164. 28Niles' National Register, August 19, 1843, p. 388. 29George R. Taylor, The Transportation Revolution (New York: Rinehart and Company, Inc., 1951), p. 213. 30Taylor, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 27, pp. 313-314 and Statistical History of the United States, p. 13, Series A-123-180. 31Ibid. 32See Carter Goodrich, Government Promotion of American Canals and Railroads, 1800-1890 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1960), and George R. Taylor, The Trans- portation Revolution, 1815-1860, Chs. 2, 3, 5. 33For canal estimates see Taylor, Transportation Revolution, p. 52. Railroad estimates and the difficulties involved in their use are found in E. R. Wicker, "Railroad Investment Before the Civil War," Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, pp. 505, 506. 34Because of the importance of the London market, Imire and more states and private promoters denominated their bonds in sterling with interest and principle payable iJlILondon. See Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., "Patterns of Amuzrican Railroad Finance, 1830-1850," Business History Review, 28 (September, 1954), p. 250. 35Harry N. Scheiber, "The Commercial Bank of Lake Erdra, 1831-1834," Business Historpreview (Spring, 1966), p. 57. 36Smith, pp. 178-179; F. Cyril James, p. 147. 109 37Canal investment reached a peak in 1840 while railroad investment peaked in 1839. The former rose from $7.5 million to $14.3 million, the latter from $1.6 million to $17.7 million. See H. Jerome Cranmer, "Canal Invest- ment, 1815-1860," Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 24 (Princeton: Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960), pp. 555-556; Albert Fishlow, American Railroads and the Transformation of the Antebellum Economy (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965). pp. 385-399. 38Frank W. Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States, Eighth Edition (New York: Capricorn Books, 1964), p. 126. , 39Niles' National Register, May 9, 1835, pp. 167- 168. 4OIbid. 41Hidy, p. 203. CHAPTER V THE END OF PROSPERITY Strains in the American economy began to appear during the first half of 1836. Continuing speculation and uncertainty over the disposition of the Federal surplus fed the uneasiness developing in many quarters over the future course of the economy. The New York State Bank Commissioners in their report of January, 1836, warned about the excessive speculation then going on.l' In April, Niles' was warning about a forthcoming crisis arising from the Federal surplus and its depositing in the deposit banks.2 The Washington Globe, a semi-official spokesman of the Jackson administration warned the deposit banks to be more conservative in their practices. The present state of the currency imposes upon the leading deposit banks the obligation of lessening their loans, calling upon other banks for regular settlements and payments of balances in specie, and thus giving check to their too extended Operations, to the raging mania for wild speculations and over- trading, and thus restore a more wholesome state in the currency of the country.3 The uncertainty and tightness in the Northern money markets, compounded by the strains placed on the New York City banks after the disastrous fire of December 1835, was gradually intensified by events in the South.4 110 111 The war in Texas curtailed Mexican specie exports to New Orleans. In 1835 these amounted to about $8.3 mil- lion, in 1836 they fell by 46 per cent to $4.5 million.5 Further aggravating the Specie position of the New Orleans banks, was the poor sugar crop of 1836.6 Fortunately for the South and the American economy in general, the cotton market remained buyont throughout most of the year, though prices were below their 1835 highs. In this chapter we will examine the domestic and foreign factors which brought the boom of the mid-1830's to its peak and prepared the ground for the panic of 1837. The money markets in America and Great Britain were to bear the brunt of the difficulties during the year. The American banking system was dealt a series of destabilizing blows by the fiscal and monetary policies of the Federal government. Adding to these problems, especially for the Eastern banks, was the worsening situation in the British financial community. Poor grain harvests and difficulties with some joint-stock banks led to a tightening of credit by the summer of 1837. It was only a matter of time before this was transmitted to the American money markets and eventually the commodity markets on both sides of the Atlantic. In the first half of this chapter we will exam- ine the effects of the Deposit Act and the Specie Circular on the banks during the year. In the second half we will hxm.at the situation in Great Britain. 112 Federal Fiscal and Monetary Policies ‘ ' in 1836 On June 23, 1836, President Jackson signed the "Act to Regulate the Deposits of the Public Money." Less than a month later, on July 11, 1836, the Secretary of the Treasury, Levi Woodbury, sent a notice, the "Specie Circular" to all receivers of public funds and to the deposit banks. Of the two actions, the first was to be far more important in it's effects on the banking system and the economy during the year that followed. In a later section of this chapter we will examine the relationship between the Specie Circular and banking activity in the last half of 1837. It is to the Deposit Act that we now direct our attention. The Deposit Act and the Deposit Banks During 1836 The Deposit Act consisted of two parts. The first, contained in sections one through twelve of the Act, dealt with the selection and regulation of deposit banks. The second, sections thirteen and fourteen, set forth the con— ditions governing the distribution of the Federal surplus 70:? which was scheduled to commence on January 1, 1837. the twelve sections that comprised the first part of the act, sections one, four, five, eight and eleven were the most important. Section one provided that a bank could hold govern- ment deposits only up to three-fourth's of the bank's paid fhxcapital. In Table 5.1 we have a listing of deposit banks 113 TABLE 5.1.--Capital Stock and United States Treasury Deposits of Deposit Banks Around June 1, 1836. ($000) Maximum Treasury Bank Capital U.S. Treasury Deposits Allowed Stock Deposits Under the Deposit Acta Maine Bank 305 185 228 Commercial B. Portsmouth 102 143 76.5 Commonwealth B. Boston 500 1085 375 Merchants' Bank Boston 1125 1098 844 Bank of Burlington, Vt. 150 54 112.5 Farmers and Mechanics Bank, Hartford 447 47 335 Mechanics' Bank New Haven 473 35 355 Arcade Bank, Providence 300 . 113 225 Mechanics and Farmers' Bank, Albany 442 185 332 Bank of America, N.Y.C. 1001 3781 1501 Manhattan Co., N.Y.C. 2050 4727 1538 Mechanics' Bank, N.Y.C. 1000 4186 1500 Girard Bank, Philadelphia 2992 2604 2244 Moyoamensing Bank, Phila. 186 400 140 Union Bank of Mary, Balti. 1846 996 1385 Franklin Bank, Baltimore 555 353 416 Bank of the MetrOpolis, Washington 500 137 375 Bank of Virginia and Branches 3240 335 2430 Bank of the State of N.C. 1206 80 905 Planters and Mechanics' Bank of South Carolina 1000 409 750 Planters Bank of the State of Georgia 535 248 401 Bank of Augusta, Georgia 900 163 675 Branch Bank of Alabama, Mobile 2255 1717 1691 Commercial Bank of New Orleans 2987 1121 2240 Union Bank of Louisiana at New Orleans 7151 1890 5363 Merchants and Manufacturers' Bank, Pittsburgh 600 93 450 Franklin Bank, Cincinnati 1000 594 750 Commercial Bank, Cincinnati 1000 478 750 Clinton Bank, Columbus, Ohio 289 441 217 Savings Institute, Louisville, Kentucky 97 476 73 Union Bank of Tennessee 2107 676 1580 State Bank of Indiana 1280 1196 960 Agency of Com. Bank of Cincinnati at St. Louis 2388 Planters' Bank of Mississippi 4149 2432 3112 Bank of Michigan, Detroit 448 1378 335 Farmers and Mechanics Bank, Detroit 200 1036 150 aSeventy-five per cent of paid in capital. We are assuming that the entire capital stock of each bank was paid in, this was not always true. Source: U.S. Congress, Senate, 24th Congress, lst Session, Senate Doc., No. 423. 114 around June 1, 1836, their capital stock and the amount of government deposits which each held. All of the deposit banks in the East coast financial centers, Boston, New York and Philadelphia, held excess treasury deposits. In the interior and the South the single deposit banks in the states of Kentucky, Indiana and Alabama held excess deposits as did the two deposit banks at Detroit Michigan. As a result of this and other requirements of the Deposit Act, the number of deposit banks more than doubled during 1836 and, The Treasury had to order the transfer of $18.3 million out of a total of $34 million on deposit in June, 1836.8 The shifting of Treasury deposits could cause these banks losing deposits to contract their lending, and perhaps their customers might not be able to renew loans or obtain their accustomed lines of credit. The loss of Treasury deposits might also entail a loss in specie, though not necessarily in a one to one ratio. Deposit banks might have adjusted to these specie losses by curtailing their lending activities and their note circulation. The infor- mation given in Table 5.2 substantiates these conclusions. The loss of Treasury deposits apparently was a more contractionary factor, insofar as bank lending was concerned, than the loss of specie. A majority, 53 per cent, of the banks which lost such deposits decreased their lending while only 32 per cent of the banks which lost 115 TABLE 5.2.--The Relationship Between Changes in United States Treasury Deposits and the Major Assets and Note Circulation of Deposit Banks, June-December 1836. A. Treasury Deposits and Bank Lending Loans and Discounts Number of Banks Treasury Deposits + 44+ (76)a 14' (24) 58 - 9 (47) 10 (53) 19 Number of Banks 53 24 [ 77 2 * X = 4.82 B. Treasury Deposits and Specie Holdings Specie Holdings Number of Banks Treasury Deposits + 40+ (69) 18- (31) 58 - 6 (32) 13 (68) 19 Number of Banks 46 31 [ 77 2 * ' X = 10.61 C. Treasury Deposits and Note Circulation Note Circulation Number of Banks Treasury Deposits + 25+ (44) 32_ (56) 57 - 2 (12) 15 (88) 17 Number of Banks 27 47 I 74 2 * X = 5.315 D. Specie and Bank Lending Loans and Discounts Number of Banks Bank Specie + 32* (70) 14 (30) 46 — 21 (68) 10 (32) 31 Number of Banks 53 24 T 77 Not significant at p = .05 aPer cent of total banks in given row. bThree banks had no note circulation. * Statistically significant at 5% level. Chi Square (X2) is a statistic that can be applied to estimate the pro- bability that the observed relationship between rows and columns is not due solely to sampling variations (chance), but actually exists. At a probability level of 5%, the X2 with one df is 3.841. If the calculated X exceeds this, we can reject the null hypothesis and accept the alternative hypothesis that there is a statistically significant rela- tionship between the columns and rows. For a discussion of chi-square analysis see Robert Ferber and P. J. Verdoorn, Research Methods in Economics and Business (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1962), pp. 73-77. Sources: United States, Congress, Senate, 24th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No. 21. 116 specie contracted their lending activities. Increases in Treasury deposits also had the same relative effect. We will later see that section eleven might account for part of the relative importance of Treasury deposits.9 Part two of the second section of the Deposit Act required that all deposits to the credit of the United States be counted as specie deposits. If desired by the drawer, all claims against government accounts at the deposit banks had to be paid in specie. This provision, part of the administration's attempt to have a hard cur- rency, was reinforced by section five which provided that a bank could not be selected nor remain as a deposit bank unless it redeemed its notes in specie. The section also provided that no bank shall: Be selected or continued . . . which shall after the fourth of July . . . issue or pay out any note or bill of a less denomination than five dollars . . . ; nor shall the notes or bills of any bank be received in payment of any debt to the United.States which shall, after the said fourth day of July . . . issue any note or bill of a less denomination than five dollars.10 These requirements should have had some affect on the bank note circulation of the deposit banks. It did, but in a way not readily apparent. The deposit banks shifted the composition of their demand liabilities away from bank notes and into demand deposits. An examination of Appendix Table B-3 shows this shift in the composition cfiidemand liabilities. In the firschalf of the year note cinnflation rose only slightly more than demand deposits 117 in per cent change. In the last half of the year, with the rapid growth in the number of deposit banks and the expansion in lending, demand deposits grew more rapidly than note circulation. Between June and November the ratio of demand deposits to note circulation rose from 58 per cent to 64 per cent. In Table 5.2 we see this shift in a different light. A majority of all deposit banks cur- tailed their note circulation. Even those banks that had increased Treasury deposits, 56 per cent also decreased their note circulation between June and the end of the year. The effects of sections two and five of the Deposit Act were to increase the demand for specie on the part of the banking system, especially the deposit banks. The prohibitions against small bank notes also increased the public's demand for specie. Further adding to the specie needs of the deposit banks was section eight which gave the Secretary of the Treasury the power to require the deposit banks to keep in their vaults an amount of specie which he deemed necessary in order to protect government deposits.11 What was the pattern of deposit bank specie holdings during 1836 and did it differ from that of the other state banks? The specie holdings of deposit banks taken as a whole increased during 1836 but so did that of state banks ‘hxgeneral. The United States Bank of Pennsylvania, on the 118 other hand lost over $5 million in specie during the year. Using the Treasury estimates of bank specie holdings we find that bank specie increased by $2.9 million or nine per cent during the year, an alternative estimate of such holdings registers a $8.8 million increase, or 28 per cent. Deposit banks increased their specie holdings by $5.3 mil- lion, or 53 per cent.13 We can tentatively conclude, given the conflicting estimates of aggregate bank specie holdings, that deposit banks increased their specie holdings to a greater extent than non-deposit banks. Since the aggregate of net specie imports and specie losses incurred by the United States Bank of Pennsylvania exceeds any estimate of increased bank specie holdings, we can also conclude that the public did increase its specie holdings during 1836. Up to this point, the sections of the Deposit Act focused on the current demand liabilities and specie hold- ings of the deposit banks. Section eleven however, con- tained a provision which could induce banks to expand their loans cm'at least alter the composition of their income earnixm; assets so as to increase their net returns. When- ever :3 bank held, during any quarter, government deposits exceeding one-quarter of its paid-in capital, it had to pay tine government interest at the rate of two per cent per annum on these excess deposits. we seertfluat all the banks as of June 1, were affected by 12 Referring to Table 5.1 119 this regulation. As we previously noted, this provision could have been one factor contributing to the strong rela- tionship between Treasury deposits and bank lending. The first eleven sections of the Deposit Act dealt with the regulation of banks which held Treasury deposits. By themselves, the regulations were sufficient to dis- arrange the banking system, at least for the time needed to select new deposit banks and shift Treasury deposits, and perhaps even longer. It was section thirteen, however, together with the Specie Circular, which bore the contem- porary blame for many of the problems which befell the American economy in early 1837. The Deposit Act: The Distribution of the Federal Surplus Section thirteen provided that: The money which shall be in the Treasury of the United States on the first day of January, eighteen hundred and thirty-seven, reserving the sum of five millions of dollars, shall be deposited with the several states, in proportion to their respective representation in the senate and the house of repre- sentatives.l4 The effect of this distribution on the banking system de- pended on the magnitude of the interstate and intrastate transfers which were required under the act and the means of trtuisfer. If the deposit banks of each state held goverrument deposits equal to the amount of funds that were to be transferred to the state, or if the pattern of gov- ernment expenditures and receipts were such that the 120 deposit banks could obtain the necessary funds for the transfer, then the payment of the distribution would not necessitate interstate transfer of funds. Even if no interstate transfers were required, the deposit banks still faces the potential loss of specie reserves if the state depository banks differed from the Federal.15 Our task will be to determine the magnitude and purposes of the transfers undertaken between the passage of the Act and the end of December and to determine what effects they had on the banking system. We will postpone until the next chapter an analysis of the role which the Act had, or supposedly had, in the monetary panic of early 1837. The Secretary of the Treasury on December 26, 1836 submitted a report to the Senate which dealt with the trans- fers ordered since June 23.16 Between the passage of the Act and this report, $38,039,385 in transfer drafts were issued, of which $25,129,385 were payable by the end of December.17 Of the latter amount, 68 per cent or approxi- mately $17.1 million were drawn for interstate transfers, as shown in Table 5.3. It is incorrect to assume that most cnreall of these transfers were undertaken solely because of the provisions of Section thirteen. The Secretary estimated that.axmccmm .mmmumb 3oz .usowuomscoo .UsmamH moonm .muummssommmmz .ucoEuo> .muflsmmemm 3oz .ocfimz ”mSOHmcH Hmmmcmua umz suflB mmpmumm mm.m u «x . mu _ we mm Hmuoa pmuaflaoaao mm “ xmec em lame a . soamuso me lave (mm lame +m~ + soamaH mamuoe soflumasouwu muoz qoflpmasonwo mpoz can mBOHm Hmmmcmua .0 me. u a up at _ em mm Hmuoa uaauamaaaam 862 mm _ Anne NH lees Hm . soamuso we Ammo an Ammo +Hm + soamcH mamuoe mmsflcaom mflommm mmcfloaom meowmw ocm mzoam Hmmmcmne .m Hp.e u Nx at _ am am Hmuoe pouaasoflao mm ’ lmev ea Ammo me I soampso we Amac (a gimme +mm + soHLaH mamuoe mflCSOOmHQ USN mCdOQ mcflpcmg xcmm cam wm3on Hmmmcmna .« .mmwa .5 Hmnfim>ozlvm Honouoo can mmma .pmsmsmumc5b cmmzpmm mxcmm uflmommo wo coaumHsouwo muoz ohm muomm< Mommz map cw mmmcmso cam mzoam ummmcmua mumumnmucH umz smmBumm mflcchflumamm 0581:.v.m mqm .mum3mHmo .mwcm>ammccmm .mmmnmb 3oz .HSOfluomccou .ccmHmH moosm .uco&um> .mnflcwmfimm 302 .mcfimz "mmpmum 30amcH soapsnfluumfla umzm me. u a up ea mm ow Hence uaaoauaemam 962 Ne fleas om Ammo mm . soampao mm Aamv (ma Amvv +>H + SOHHGH mamuos QOwHMHDOHHO muoz COHHMHDOHHU OHOZ UCM m3OHm HmwaMHB QOH¥59flHHmHQ #02 .U me. u a up we _ mm me Hence aaaoaeaaaam 562 me a heme ea Amps km . onmuso mm lees Ike lame +mH + sonaH mamuoa mmcfloaom mflommm mmcfloaom wflomaw can mBOHm Hmmmcmua coausnwuumwa #02 .m mo. u a up an 1 He em Hmuoe uptoHMHemam uoz ma _ Ammo mm Ines we . zoauuao mm ital use 16ml +eH + onLaH mamuoa mHCDOUmHD UGM mCMOH wcflocoq xcmm cam mmzoam nmmmcmna .QOHusnflHuwwo #02 .< .mmmH nonfimowo can mmma .b Hmnfim>oz|vm Honouoo cmm3umm mxcmm uflwommo mo sowumasonwo muoz cam mummmd Hoflmz msu ca momsmso cam #04 coausnflnumfio msu mm cmumuwmmmomz mBOHm Hmmmsmns mumumumucH uoz cmm3umm mflnmcoflumHmm mnBII.m.m mqmde 127 lending and specie holdings grew more rapidly than other banks. Movements in Treasury deposits, however, had a greater influence on lending than did movements in specie holdings. In the June to November period transfer drafts did appear to affect the lending and note creation policies of the banks. When we came to the last two months of the year when banks could prepare for the distribution, we saw that their lending policies became less expansionary. It is not possible to say with any degree of certainty that it was only the preparations for the distribution that altered bank policies in the last two months of 1836. Other factors were already at play by this time. Perhaps more importantly we do not have comparative information for non-deposit banks during this period. But it is again clear that the Deposit Act did influence the behavior of banks governed by it. Whether the Deposit Act fed the fires of inflation is a question which cannot be definitively answered. The evidence, fragmentary as it is, is affirmative. We have just seen that movements in Treasury deposits did influence bank behavior. Between January 1835 and November 1836, the loans and discounts of deposit banks increased by 143 per cent and note circulation by 168 per cent. In comparison, the national figures for all banks was 48 per cent and 44 per cent.22 As the relative size of the assets and liabili- ties of the deposit banks did not vary greatly during these 128 years, it means that the rate of growth for all banks is overstated. If we accept the tentative conclusion that the Deposit Act did feed the inflationary pressures of the mid-1830's, can we then determine by how much it did? One can perform the Operations of counterfactural history and attempt to determine what the growth rate of banking ac- tivity would have been if there had been no Deposit Act. But the data is too fragmentary and the assumptions too uncertain. There are many assumptions that might be needed but perhaps more important than facile economic assumptions is a political one. Can we assume away the political realities of the time that produced the Deposit Bank? This seems impossible. Our conclusions on the effects of the Deposit Act during the last half of 1836 are somewhat at variance with those of Peter Temin's in his "The Jacksonian Economy." The main reason for this is that Temin, along with Tember- lake, focus primary attention On the relationship between the distribution segment of the Deposit Act and the events of early 1837.23 When Temin does briefly look at the pos- sible effects of the Act during the last half of 1836, he approaches the problem in an unusual and eventually er- roneous way. The first and basic assumption made by Temin is that if the Distribution had any effect on banks, it was 129 through the shifting of specie brought about by the transfer of the Treasury deposits. We have already seen in this chapter that the available information does not support this assumption. Temin then implicitly assumes that the first part of the Deposit Act had no effect on bank behavior. Rather, he concentrates on the movement of specie during the last half of 1836. Finally when he does look at the effects of the Treasury transfers he assumes that as they did not cause a breakdown in the banking system in 1836, they did not cause the panic in 1837. Temin notes that there exists in the literature an argument that, The Secretary of the Treasury, Levi Woodbury, shifted the public deposits between regions in late 1836 to avoid a large demand for specie at the actual distribution and that this shift placed intolerable strains on the banking system. One might suppose that Temin then attempted to determine the magnitude and purpose of interstate transfers during the last half of the year and the effects which this may have had on the banks involved. He did not. He first looked at the total amount of transfers made in the last half of the year and then at the net changes in Treasury deposits during that time. In concluding fur; analysis, Temin first notes that, Only five states lost public deposits between June 20 and December 19, 1836. Of these losses, only two exceeded a quarter of a million dollars, and the losses from all states totaled just under $1.5 million. It is clear that the net effect of the Treasury's actions was not to reallocate the government deposits among the different regions of the country. 130 This conclusion is not surprising. We have already seen that Secretary Woodbury estimated that less than $2 million was transferred for this purpose in 1836. This sum amounted to less than 13 per cent of the interstate trans- 26 What is fer drafts drawn and paid during the period. surprising is that the data cited by Temin cannot be used to support his conclusion. Changes in Treasury deposits reflect not only transfer drafts but also expenditures and receipts of Treasury revenue. Thus Temin should have at least measured net transfer flows, not net deposit changes. Whereas only five states lost Treasury deposits in the last half of 1836, six states had net transfer outflows as we saw in Table 5.4. Of these six, New York State alone had a deficit of $6.86 million, all of the outflow coming from New York City. Michigan had a net outflow of $2.16 million, Ohio lost $1.34 million and Indiana lost $880,000 27 Transfer drafts because of interstate transfer drafts. did not reallocate government deposits among regions as much as they did among different states and as we have already shown this did influence bank behavior. Finally, Temin remarks that while the distribution did not cause the suspension of 1837 it was a hardship on individual banks. He then cites as examples the states of New York and Michigan which lost $570,000 and $430,000 .in Treasury deposits respectively, between June and Decem- loer.28 Even looking just at changes in Treasury deposits 131 the figures cited by Temin do not tell the entire story. Though New York State deposit banks lost $570,000 in Treas- ury deposits, those in New York City lost at least four times that amount during the June to December period.29 In the next chapter we will see that the distribution contri- buted to the suspension of the New York City banks in 1837 though it did not cause it in any unicausal fashion. With the enactment of the Deposit Act, the banks involved found themselves under increasing pressure. The administrative rules of the first part of the act, especially section one, caused large transfers of government deposits. After November, the banks had to prepare themselves for the distribution, but they had to do it almost alone. The government did not provide any large scale aid to prepare the banks for the distribution. But this was not to be the end of Federal policies which affected the banking system, not just the deposit banks, in the last half of 1836. The Specie Circular and the Banking System Within a month of the passage of the Deposit Act, the Jackson administration supposedly dealt another blow to the banking system, this time in the form of the "Specie Circular." The Specie Circular supposedly had two effects on the American economy. It dampened land sales and it caused specie to move from Eastern to mid-Western and South- Vkstern banks. We will concentrate our attention on the 132 relationship between the Circular and land sales during the last half of the year. In so doing we will briefly examine the argument that the Circular caused specie to be shifted from the East to the banks in the land-sale states. On July 11, 1836, a circular was sent to receivers of Public Funds and the deposit banks instructing them specifically not to accept in payment for public lands after August 15, . . . nothing, except what is directed by the existing laws, namely, gold and silver, and, in the proper cases, Virginia land script; provided, that until the 15th of December next (1836), the same indulgences heretofore extended as to the kind of money received, may be continued for any quantity of land not exceeding three hundred and twenty acres to each purchaser who is an actual settler, or bana fide resident in the states where the sales are made.30 The stated purpose of the Circular was to curtail further speculation in public land sales as well as to safeguard the currency. This latter purpose being a con- tinuation of the Jacksonian policy of substituting specie 31 for paper currency. Though it was announced on July 11, the Specie Circular did not become partially effective until August 16 and fully effective until mid-December. Thus for approxi- mately one-half of the third quarter it was not effective against large purchases, those supposedly made by land speculators. Yet as we see in Appendix Table A-6, public land sales fell sharply during the third quarter. It should 133 be noted that sales during the second quarter were the highest for any quarter during the ante-bellum period. Land sales in the last half of 1836 were 25 per cent below the levels of the first half. This might not seem that significant a decrease in sales given the record sales of the second quarter, but prior to 1836 second half sales were less than first half sales only in 1819, 1820, and 1825.32 The first two years, 1819-1820, were during the post-Napoleonic depression and 1825 was a year of financial difficulty.33 Can we attribute the decrease in land sales to the Specie Circular or were there other factors at work which in combination with the Circular depressed land sales in the last half of 1836? It may be helpful for analytical purposes to divide the demand for land into two parts, a speculative and a factor demand for land. Today when an individual buys common stock which yields little or no current dividend income, we assume it is because of the expectation of future capital apprecia- tion“ This depends on the future earnings of the company. Tfiua same principle applies to land, among other forms of speKNJlation. Speculators purchased land with the belief thal: they could resell it at a price which would yield thenlea profit sufficient to warrant the risks undertaken.34 The speculative demand depends first on the amount and.1nerns on which credit could be obtained, and secondly, 134 on the resale market, the latter in turn also depending on the credit market. Credit facilities were thus central to the speculative demand, and the Specie Circular allegedly dried up the credit streams which fed the land speculators. Western banks stopped discounting and sold all Eastern funds for specie in the expectation that they would need it for land purchases and as a defense against the Treasury. In the short-run, when the supply of land is rela- tively fixed and the ability to shift land from one use to another is limited, the speculative demand for land is important in determining the level of demand. In the long- run, the usefulness or productivity of land, be it in cotton, grain or urban real estate, and the demand for the good or service produced with the land becomes the main determinants of the level of demand.36 The close proximity of the Specie Circular to the Deposit Act makes it difficult to separate out the effects of these two events on the banking system, assuming that they were the only factors influencing the banking system during the last half of 1836. However, we shall see that these were not the only factors at work during this time and therefore, our conclusions on the effects of the Specie Circular, just as those on the Deposit Act, cannot be acceptable as absolute. Ideally, a comparison should be made between banks in land sale states and those in other states between July and.the beginning of October. The latter date reflects the 135 fact that land sales fell sharply during the third quarter. The use of data for November and December might also entail the danger of including the effects of banks preparing for the distribution. Information of this type is available only for deposit banks. It would be simpler if we could assume that non-deposit banks behaved in the same manner as deposit banks, but we have already seen that they did not. The information on deposit banks is given in Table 5.6. Since the results are not statistically significant, we cannot assume that the decline in bank lending was related solely to the location of banks in land sale areas. What if the results had been significant, could we then infer that the Specie Circular led to a decline in bank lending for land speculation purposes? It is unlikely that we could. All we know is that aggregate bank lending declined in deposit banks in land sale states. What per cent of this was due to a curtailment in land loans is not known. Furthermore, we cannot assume that only banks in the West were involved in supplying funds for land specula- tion.37 Rising interest rates in the East might have con- tributed to the drying up of funds available for land speculation. First of all, the high interest rates may have made investment in commercial paper more attractive. Secondly, the high rates were due to a tightening credit 136 TABLE 5.6.--Comparison of the Changes in Major Assets and Liabilities of Deposit Banks in Land Sale and Non—land Sale States, July—October, 1836.a A. United Loans and Specie Circu— States Discounts lationC Treasury Deposits Land Sale Statesb 6+ 10 9+ 7‘ 2+ 13‘ 6+ 8’ Non-Land Sale States 24 ll 21 l4 19 15 24 10 B. Land Sales and Bank Lending Loans and Discounts Total Banks Land Sales 6+ (37) 10‘ (63) 16 Non-Land Sales 24 (69) ll (31) 35 Not significant Total Banks 30 21 51 at p = .05 C. Land Sales and Specie Holdings Specie Total Banks Land Sales 9+ (56) 7’ (44) I 16 Non-Land Sales 21 (60) 14 (40) 35 Not significant Total Banks 30 21 I 51 at p = .05 D. Land Sales and Note Circulation Note Circulation Total Banks Land Sales 2+ (13) 13‘ (87) 15 Non-Land Sales 19 (56) 15 (44) 34 Not significant Total Banks 21 28 [ 49 at p = .05 aFirst reporting data in October not later than October 15. Only Banks submitting reports for both dates are included. bLand Sales States: Ohio, Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Missouri, Alabama, Mississippi, and Louisiana. CTwo banks had no treasury deposits during this period. Source: Table 5.2. 137 situation further lessening the flow of funds to the West for land speculation. Thus in the Eastern money markets a smaller supply of loanable funds might have been shifted into the commercial paper market to a greater extent than previously, to the detriment of the land market. The decline in land sales during the second half of 1836 does indicate that the Specie Circular had some effect on the market for public lands. As we have just seen the information available is insufficient to deter- mine if the effects of the Circular worked mainly through the supply of credit available to speculators and their potential customers. Our discussion so far has assumed that the Specie Circular brought about a decline in land sales through its effects on the supply of credit, but what about the demand for land? What other factors might have contributed to a decline in the demand for land, both its speculative and factor components? It is possible that the Specie Circular made speculators more wary about buying land. They may have believed that the boom was coming to an end and that it was better to try to sell land already held and not jpurchase additional land.38 The factor demand for land may have also contributed ‘to a decline in land sales. Directly, farmers and planters Inight have decided it was not the time to buy land from the ZFederal government. Indirectly, speculators might have :found it more difficult to sell land to farmers and planters. 138 The demand for agricultural land is a derived demand, depending on the profitability of the products grown on it. In the New South this meant cotton, in the North-Central states it meant grain. Cotton prices in 1836 were below their 1835 highs and were falling throughout the latter part of 1836 al- though total receipts reached a decade peak in this year. Given the period of time needed between the preparation of new cotton lands and the harvesting of the first crop, a short-run decline in cotton prices might not be that sig- nificant.39 Falling prices or at least prices below their 1835 peak could have combined with rising costs of production to produce a squeeze on profits. According to the estimates of Conrad and Meyer, the average price per dollar invested 40 A profit squeeze is not the best in slaves declined. inducement for further commitment in cotton lands. The decline in land sales might have been due to these factors. It might have also been due in part to the Specie Circular and perhaps the political insecurity arising out of the Texas rebellion. In the North-Central states wheat and corn prices rose during 1836, but this was mainly due to poor harvests. ‘What effect this had on the demand for land is difficult to judge. Farmers might not have been willing to add on to their existing holdings. On the other hand, the high prices 139 might have induced farmers to expand their holdings or go further West. But as we do not know how quickly farmers did respond to the poor harvests of the period we cannot say what actually happened. Land sales in the North- Central states rose in 1836. Since we have only annual data we do not know when or even if land sales declined during the last half of the year. In both the South and the North-Central region, the agricultural outlook was not propitious towards the end of the year. But what effect this had on the demand for land we do not know. We do know however that land sales fell in the third and fourth quarters of the year. The Specie Circular was announced in July and though it did not legally effect land sales to any extent until mid- August, it is difficult to say that it did not contribute to the decline in land sales. It has sometimes been thought that land sales during 1834-1836 acted as a safety valve decreasing the infla- tionary pressures of the times by drawing money away from the market for goods and services which supposedly had less supply elasticity than public land. A corollary of this line of reasoning is that the Specie Circular fed the infla- tionary fires by reducing this leakage.41 What is left unanswered by this line of reasoning is the specification of the alternative sources of demand for bank funds. It is further assumed that the banks were 140 willing to supply these demands. Given that banks in the land-sale states during the last half of 1836 had loanable funds which they did not want to lend for land purchases, what were the alternative demands for these funds? Bankers discounted bills for local merchants and cotton factors. The credit needs of these individuals depended on the demand of farmers, cotton planters and other consumers for manufactured goods. The argument that the demand of merchants and factors for credit could have absorbed the loanable funds released by the decline in land sales sup- poses that the demand for manufactured goods increased. But this was a time when the economic climate in the agri- cultural regions differed greatly from that of 1835. Bankers did not have to loan out the funds previ- ously lent for land purchases. They could have done nothing, and by so doing decrease their demand liabilities and per- haps put themselves in better shape if they were deposit banks, for the forthcoming distribution. Non-deposit banks Inight have decided that this was not the time to extend their activities given the Specie Circular, the forthcoming distribution and the problems in the agricultural regions. Finally bankers could have purchased securities as an alter- native investment outlet. Thus the funds released by the Specie Circular did not automatically have to go into loans that increased aggregate demand and further stimulated the inflationary pressures. ,3 "1 ii .' 141 Temin believed that the Specie Circular most likely did rechannel purchasing power and thus increased infla- tionary pressures in the last half of the year. He points out that, "prices continued to rise in late 1836 while land sales fell."42 But as we have already seen, the deposit banks in the land-sale states decreased their lending in the last half of 1836. Even if the non-deposit banks ex- panded their lending so that the total amount of loans increased, this still did not mean any large increase in aggregate demand. Only if we further assumed that all funds were lent for purposes which directly and immediately increased aggregate demand could there be some justifica- tion for Temin's argument. Land sales in the last half of 1836 were less than $4 million below the levels of the first half of the year. Given that Temin uses an estimate of $1.5 million for United States gross national product in 1839, it is very hard to see how four million dollars could have been that crucial in maintaining inflationary pressures.43 While we cannot find any justification to support the hypothesis that the Specie Circular increased infla- tionary pressures, what about the more general hypothesis about the effect of land sales on the price level? Accord- ing to Temin, The sale of land acted as a 'sink' for the extra money supply of the mid-1830's because unlimited quantities could be bought without raising the price. 142 If these funds were directed elsewhere, they would cause prices to rise and the inflation to continue. 44 We have already seen the assumptions about alterna- tive sources of demand for bank credit that this argument entails. But let us look at this hypothesis from a slightly different point of View. This hypothesis implicitly assumes that loans for land speculation decreased by an equal amount the supply of loanable funds available for activities that directly in- creased aggregate demand. Given the performance of banks during the boom period it is hard to imagine such an interest- inelastic supply of bank credit. Suppose that the supply was inelastic, this still might have contributed to the inflationary pressures. Mer- chants who discounted bills at a bank might have been will- ing to pay higher interest rates if they could pass the costs on to the consumers. There is no reason to believe that this did not occur in the inflationary climate of the mid-1830's. Finally by drawing funds, especially Eastern funds, into land speculation, less funds were available for the purchase of capital equipment thus slowing down the rate of growth of aggregate supply. There is no evidence of either a quantitative or qualitative nature to support the hypothesis that land speculation was counter-inflation- ary. The Specie Circular appears to have had some effect cum land sales but did it also cause a shifting of specie 143 from Eastern banks to those in the West and South-West? There are three annual series available showing bank specie holdings by region. These are given in Table 5.7. Taking into account the differences in the estimates it appears that banks in the East did not lose any significant amount of specie to those in the land-sale states.45 But these are annual estimates and we do not know much about bank specie holdings during the last half of 1836. What information we do have indicates that banks, at least in New York City and Pennsylvania did not lose specie until the start of the fourth quarter of 1836. By this time banks in the land-sales states did not need that much specie as land sales had already fallen sharply. The specie holdings of the New York City Safety Fund banks were 22 per cent higher in September 1836 than the holdings of July. New York City deposit bank specie holdings rose every month from July through September while the specie holding of Pennsylvania banks, excluding the United States Bank, in November were 12 per cent above the June levels.46 The Specie Circular apparently did not cause a noticeable shifting of specie from banks in the East to those in the South-West and the mid-West. The Circular apparently contributed to a decline in the public's confidence in bank notes. Imagine the situation around July 1836. The Jackson administration had been attempting for more than a year to eliminate small 144 .mmm .a .Amaaa .nnona spannm>ans pnn>nnm "mapannsaov Home muowmm mmOHum cuwpmmz .muumm .m mmaose .NNH .m .Ammma ..OcH .wcmmEoo ocm coupoz .3 .3 “show Bozo wfiocoom cMHGOmxomb 0:9 .cHEOB Hmumm unconsom .mflcm>H>macmm mo xcmm mmpmpm pmpwco moppaoxmm e.m+ ~.H+ m.a+ m. + m. + m. . snumm m.m+ ~.H+ ~.N+ m.m+ m. + o Moxmsumpmcmm cm> a.m+ H.H+ m.H+ H. + v. I m. + ansmmmua mmma mo one can mmmH mo ppm cmmemm mmsmno m.vm m.> m.m m.> v.HH m.~ mnnmm m.mm >.m v.5 m.h «.ma O.m Homeumumcmm cm> o.mm >.m m.h H.n >.HH m.m mupmmmua mmma mo cam m.am O.m m.m 0.5 m.oa m.m mznnom o.Hm m.v m.m H.m ~.NH m.m memfinmumcmm cm> H.Nm m.v o.m 0.5 H.NH v.~ hupmmmua mmwa mo cam cumummz cumummz :Hmpmmm capsmaps uwmm Hayes suuoz supom susom mappwz spuoz Aooo.ooomv .mmmHImmmH .coflmmm xp .mxsmm cumum ca owomdm mo cofipspfiuumflonu.s.m mqmda 145 bank notes from circulation. A bill passed in 1835 would become effective on July 4, prohibiting the government from accepting or using bank notes smaller than $10. Section five of the Deposit Act all but eliminated the use of a bank note, if the section was enforced. Then, on July 11, the Specie Circular was announced. No wonder some people might become wary of bank notes. In a letter to the Baring's written in April, 1837, Biddle remarked that, The crusade against banks and the discrimination at the Land Offices between specie and bank paper has not been without its effect on the less intelligent part of our population, whom it has inclined to hoard specie. As far as we can determine from the existing infor- mation, the Specie Circular contributed to the decline in land sales during the last half of 1836. Its effects on banks were minimal in terms of specie movements between banks. It might have, however, weakened public confidence in bank notes and thus banks. In this latter instance, the Specie Circular was one of several factors which de- stabilized the banking system in the latter part of 1836 and early 1837. Up to now we have looked at the Deposit Act and the Specie Circular and the effects which they had on the bank- ing system and the economy. We will now turn to the situa— tion in the New York Money market to see if the events of the last half of the year weakened the city banks so that they could not withstand the pressures of 1837. 146 The New York Money Market in the Last Half of 1836 By the 1830's the financial and commercial center 48 During the last of the United States was New York City. half of 1836, the New York money market began to evidence signs of strain. Short-term interest rates began to rise in April and in July, the same month that the Bank of Eng- land raised its discount rate, the increase became more rapid. Domestic exchange rates on other East-coast centers and the South, which were stable throughout 1835 also began to move. What happened to the city banks during these months and what effects did the Deposit Act and the Specie Circular have on the banks of New York City? Information is not available on a monthly basis for all banks in New York City. However, we do have data for the Safety Fund banks for the first month of each quarter 49 in 1836. We also have fairly complete information, as given in Table 5.8, on the deposit banks between July and September and it becomes complete for the months of October until December. This is due to the Treasury department's adding of new deposit banks until October. To improve our understanding of the actions of the deposit banks we will also look at the behavior of the three leading deposit banks [during the same time period. This latter information is «given in Appendix Table B-12. Between July and September, the Safety Fund banks (expanded their lending activities, although it was a small 147 .ON .2 .mmm .02 us0Esooo >HQE0mm4 .OOflmm0m spew .2HQE0mmfi .0u0pm 2H0» 302 .mma .m .0pc0>0m mpamnpm .0cupom .mmaloma .mHHImHH .moanmoa .mm .om .02 #:055000 00502 .coflmm0m umH .mm0uo Isoo Spmm .00502 .mm0uocoo m0p0pm p0¢wa2 .matm .mm .Hm .02 “COEdooo 0u0s0m .COHmm0m ppm .mmmumsou spvm .0u0c0m .mm0nmcou m0umpm p0pflc2 "mmoupom .wam.omm.maw m0 hmma .H mumpcmb mo mm mpflmom0p 2H5000HB mpmwa 0cupomp .0 can a c003u0n m0mwum mocmm0uomflp 0n» .muflmom0p wusmm0ns mcH>H0O0H Hfl0nu ou Hofium mxcmp 080m How c0>flm 0H03 manom0n md .bmma .hapb Hem NH .202 on H0pouoo now ma .H0Q60um0m How NH .umsms¢ How OH .2pr MOM O0H0>oo mxcmp 0>Hmo .emma .SHaa now NH .202 Op H0QE0u20m “Om ma .umcmsd MOM ma .mapb How O0H0>oo mxcmp pnmflmp .rna wean ou Onmm 0cpb Eoum munom0n mcfimpcoo wash «puma 202 cu spam Hands Eoum manom0u mcflmucoo >02 .suh scum: on pumm wumsup0m Eoum mpHOQ0H mcflmucoo some: .O0ms we 0mmn0>0 0gp .xcmn 0 2p nucoa 0su How c0>wo we uuommu 0co gasp 0uoE c0£30 named amnm perm mama eaten mean wmmm ommw mmmm wmva mommm >02 maom wmom mvmv mmhm ooomm scum: pmamaa momv mwmm moavm H0980000 «mafia HmHv mmhm mamam H0QE0>o2 mamaa mvam «new mnmmm H0pouoo mmoma mmmw snow Nmmmm H09E0um0m nmava mmmw Hmom Hammm umsmp< ammMH mmam mkma mooem saga mnemom0o omuamom0o pcofluma pmucsoomflo 0um>flum musmmmue Isouflo 0HO0Qm paw manoq syncs nmunum amped: n n Aooomo .emmH sasauemma saga wpfiu xnow 302 .mxcmm uflmommo mo wwaflawnmflq cam wuwmmd Honmzll.m.m mam¢s 148 increase, amounting to only approximately three per cent. Recalling our previous discussion on the lending activities of deposit banks in general it comes as no surprise that during the same period, city deposit banks expanded their loans by almost 37 per cent. By January, 1837 loans and discounts were less than $1 million below their September, 1836 level. As we will soon see there is other information which indicates that there was some decrease in lending during part of the fourth quarter. Contrary to contem- porary and later writers who believed that the Specie Cir- cular drew specie away from the East, the Safety Fund Banks increased their specie holdings by approximately 20 per cent during the third quarter.50 The actions of the city deposit banks can perhaps give us more information as to what happened during the last half of the year. The deposit banks as we have just noted increased their lending during the third quarter. But the three leading deposit banks in the city, the Bank Of America, Bank of the Manhattan Company, and the Mechanics Bank, decreased their loans and discounts by $1.2 million during these months.51 This occurred at a time when their Specie holdings increased by 26 per cent. From what we have previously seen it appears that the actions of these three deposit banks differed from those of city banks in general. 149 One possible explanation for this lies in the move- ment of Treasury deposits. In August the three banks lost $1.8 million in such deposits while the total losses for all city deposit banks was $1.1 million. This indicates that perhaps only these banks lost deposits, and most of these went to banks outside the city. An examination of Treasury deposits in the city banks confirms this. No other city deposit bank lost Treasury deposits during this period. In September, however, the other city deposit banks began to curtail their lending activities, as they too, 52 The banks responded to were losing Treasury deposits. these losses by contracting their lending, this taking place during September, October and the early part of November. Deposit bank lending fell by Slightly over 14 per cent during the months of September to November. The Shifting lending policies of the city banks were reflected in the movement of Short-term interest rates in New York during the last half of the year. Interest rates rose from 12 per cent at the end of June to 36 per cent at the end of October. For the remainder of the year they fluctu- ated between 24 per cent and 30 per cent. The loss of Treasury deposits was possibly more serious than the monthly data indicates. These figures are for net changes and thus do not reflect the total turn- tjver of Treasury deposits during a month. The turnover of 150 deposits posed serious problems for the banks involved because of the regulations in the Deposit Act requiring Specie payment on Treasury deposits when demanded. Sup- pose a bank lost a net of $500,000 in Treasury deposits during the month, this might have entailed a concommitant loss os specie. During the same month, however, the turn- over in the Treasury deposits could have been some multiple of the net change. Thus, the bank, while only losing a half million in Treasury deposits might lose more than that in Specie. Unlike the transfers which would be authorized for the Distribution banks did not have much forewarning about drafts which were drawn to meet the Section One requirements of the Deposit Act or normal expenditures of the government. We have previously seen in Table 5.3 that approximately $8.8 million in interstate transfer drafts were drawn, and payable, on city banks between the end of June and the middle of December. Other deposit banks outside the city were also experiencing similar shifts in Treasury deposits. It would have been helpful to have information on bankers' balances in the city during this period to see if they underwent any Significant changes, but unfortunately, this information was not available for 1836. We can obtain another indication of the changing Situation in the New York money market by looking at the domestic exchange rates. 151 Just as Foreign exchange rates reflect the trading conditions between countries as well as the climate of the money and capital markets, so domestic exchange rates can also be used to give one an indication of the conditions of trade between different cities and regions of a country. In Appendix Table B-lS, we have the discount or premium on domestic exchange--sight bills-—in New York City, the bills being drawn on some of the important commercial centers of the country. An increase in the discount rate, which is the same as a fall in the price of the bill, results from either an increase in the supply of bills--assuming demand remains constant--; a decrease in the demand--assuming the supply as constant--; or some combination of demand and supply Shifts causing the new market price to be below the old price. The opposite holds for a decrease in the dis- count rate or a rise in the premium. Throughout 1835 and during the first half of 1836, the prices of domestic exchange remained stable. In June, changes started to occur, the price Of bills on Boston fell, while the discount on Southern bills, Signifying a falling price of bills, doubled, perhaps, due to the de- clining price of cotton. In July, exchange on Philadelphia and Baltimore rose slightly in price, rising grain prices and the loss of Specie holdings in New York banks might have contributed to this increase, Since the city banks could try to get exchange on these cities with the hope 152 of obtaining Specie. Whatever the causes of these changes, the most Significant fact was the changes themselves, especially in the South, coming after more than a year and a half of price stability. By the end of 1836, the New York City banks had temporarily eased their contractionary policies. Some might have thought that the difficulties were over, but the reverse was true. The banks during the last two months continued to lose specie, and facing them in 1837 was the Distribution. Meanwhile, across the Atlantic, events were unfolding that were to have the most serious effects on New York City banks and the other banks of America during 1837. The British Money and Commodity Markets During 1836 The English financial community showed increasing signs of distress towards the end of 1836. Nowhere was this more evident than in the Anglo-American trade and the condition of the Bank of England. Although earnings from cotton exports reached a peak in 1836, the declining price of cotton posed serious problems for the firms engaged in the cotton trade. To see why this was so, let us look for a moment at the cotton operations of the firm of Alexander Brown and Sons of Baltimore, one of the leading houses in the Anglo-American trade. Utilizing the services of coastal factors resident in the cotton ports--and also to some extent those of 153 inland factors . . . the Browns offered in normal times to advance apparently the full value of cotton ship- ments consigned to the Liverpool branch. The advance was made in the form of bills drawn by the exporter on the Liverpool House and endorsed by the Brown agent. However, 1836 did not represent "normal times;" even in January, Brown Brothers limited advances to three- quarters or four-fifths of the present value of the cotton shipment.54 Advances were made on the present value, and it was here that the danger existed. What would happen to the Liverpool house of the Browns or of other Anglo-American firms if bills were drawn on them with the expectation of cotton selling in the range of nine to eleven pence per pound, but the cotton could only be sold for eight or nine pence? Some losses would be incurred, or if the firms were lucky, only their profit margins would be out. By the end of 1836, prices had fallen to a range of seven and one-half to eleven and one-quarter pence, while they had been as high aS nine to twelve pence during the months of March to June. If credit facilities were available, some houses might decide to hold the cotton off the market in the hOpe of selling at higher prices, but the London money market was having difficulties. These difficulties in London meant additional problems for the houses dealing in cotton. The eXport of finished cotton goods, just as much as the importation and production of cotton, depended on the availability of credit. 154 Rising interest rates in London, placed the Anglo- American houses in a two-way squeeze. The demand for raw cotton fell as producers found it more expensive to obtain credit. The cotton houses also saw their costs increasing as they had to discount bills in London or with Joint-Stock banks at a higher rate of discount. Any trade which was dependent on easy money and rising prices, as was the cotton trade, was vulnerable when the monetary conditions changed and prices began to fall. By mid-1836 the Bank of England had begun to pursue a more restrictive monetary policy. At least until May the monetary situation in London showed none of the signs of tightness which was then being experienced in the United States.56 The ready availability of credit in London was attributed to the rapid growth of joint-stock banks and the policies of the Bank of England. Between 1826, when they were first allowed to form and July, 1833 34 such banks were established; by the end of 57 1835, there were 60. For a discussion of the inflationary policies of the Bank of England, Clapham is still a very good source.58 Throughout the last quarter of 1835, the Short-term market rate of interest in London was 3.75 per cent per annum, it fell to three and one-half per cent by March of 1836, and it reached its low point of three and one-quarter 59 per cent in April and May. The Bank of England's dis- cpunt rate was four per cent during this period. The 155 situation changed rapidly during late spring and early summer. By June, the market rate had risen three-quarters of one per cent, and by the end of the year, it was two and one-half points above the April-May low, a 77 per cent increase. An index of stock market Share prices which stood at 113.6 in May, fell to 94.1 in November before 60 The causes of this recovering slightly in December. dramatic reversal are to be found in the attempts of the Bank of England to curtail its Specie losses at a time when the poor grain harvests were increasing domestic grain prices and specie exports. During the last quarter of 1835 and the first of 1836 the Bank of England increased its specie holdings. By the second quarter, the accumulation came to a halt. For the rest of the year, the Bank lost Specie. It has some- times been inferred that this loss was induced, at least partially, by the economic difficulties then occurring in the United States, and especially, the Specie Circular. The crisis in the United States, under way even before the appearance of the Specie Circular, became more severe with its issue. Monetary pressure com- municated itself to Britain through the commercial and financial connexions which had grown up in the previous few years. American traders liquidated much of their available holdings in London and cut down their imports. American securities were dumped in the British market and the cash (specie) remitted to America.6 Why just blame it on the Specie Circular, which we have previously seen was not that powerful an influence on the banks of America, why not also blame the specie losses 156 incurred by the Bank of England on the Deposit Act? The answer is simple, the facts do not support such statements. According to W. B. Smith, the United States imported approxi- mately £506,000 or $2.462 million, in Specie from England between October 1, 1835 and September 30, 1836, but the Bank of England lost approximately 52.6 million between April and September, 1836.62 Palmer, the Governor of the Bank of England attri- buted 2.3 million pounds of this loss to eXportation to America.63 Part of this Specie loss could have gone in- directly to the United States by way of France as a result of the French indemnity payment, but Palmer estimated that the Bank lost £100,000 in specie to France between April and December.64 Palmer's estimates are grossly inaccurate. Even if we assume that the entire American specie inflow from England during fiscal 1836 took place between April and September, it still amounted to Slightly less than 20 per cent of the specie lost by the Bank of England and only 23 per cent of the amount which Palmer claims was sent to the United States. The Bank of England was losing specie during the last half of 1836. We have seen that contrary to the claims of the Governor of the Bank, Palmer, most of the Specie did not go to the United States. Now we will see where the Specie did go. It was these losses and the rmlicies that the Bank of England pursued in an attempt 157 to stem them that brought about the monetary stringency in London which seriously weakened the financial underpinnings of the Anglo-American trade. The directors of the Bank of England believed that the losses could be attributed to the lending policies of the joint-stock banks and those of the Anglo-American houses. In the latter instance they followed the lead of Palmer. The major Anglo-American houses were Baring Brothers and Company; W. and J. Brown and Company; F. de Lizardi and Company; Morrison, Cryden and Company; T. Wiggin and Company; T. Wilson and Company; and George Wildes and Company.65 The joint-stock banks began to encounter difficulties in November and T. Wiggin and Company asked the other Anglo-American houses for aid in December.66 The first joint-stock bank to fail was the Agri- cultural and Commercial Bank of Ireland.. A run on the other Irish banks was prevented when the Bank of England sup- plied £2,000,000 in bullion to these banks.67 On November 28, the manager of the Northern and Central Bank of Manchester--this bank had 39 branches--for some unknown reason left £108,000 in a cab. This helped to start a run on the bank, which was halted when the Bank of England again came to the rescue. It eventually provided £1,370,000 in aid.68 The aid provided by the Bank of England as well as the attempts of other banks, mainly joint-stock banks, in 158 Ireland and England to build up their Specie reserves most likely accounted for a great portion of the Bank of Eng- land's Specie losses. Adding to this internal drain was an external drain. This was necessitated by the large grain imports from the continent because of poor harvest. The United States also had a poor harvest and this probably helped to further increase world grain prices. British imports of wheat, barley, oats and flour in 1836 were 110 per cent of their 1835 levels. Wheat prices averaged 23 per cent, barley 10 per cent, and oats prices five per cent above their 1835 levels.69 The Bank responded to the losses of Specie by raising its discount rate and applying selective credit restraints. The discount rate was raised first to four and one-half per cent on July 21, 1836. This was the first change in the discount rate Since July 1827. On September 1, the discount rate was again raised by one-half per cent. Thus in about two months the rate was raised by 25 per cent above its pre- July level. The Bank of England also attempted to apply selec- tive credit controls by limiting the types of bills it accepted for discounting. It refused to discount, or accept as security for loans, bills drawn on Anglo-American merchant houses. This action affected not only these houses but many joint-stock banks which discounted the bills of these houses and then sold them in the London discount market.70 159 In normal times the selective credit restraints of the Bank of England did not seriously hamper the major houses, who, because of their size, did not usually redis- count with bill brokers or the Bank of England.71 But these were unusual times, the smaller houses had been using the facilities of the joint-stock banks. Three of the larger Anglo-American houses, Wiggins, Wilson, and Wilde-- the "3 W's"--had approximately £885,000 in acceptances held by the Bank of England at the end of July.'72 It appears that these actions on the part of the Bank were not sufficient to limit the activities of the Anglo-American houses. In October Palmer, the Governor of the Bank, applied what we now call "moral suasion," to the Anglo-American houses. He told representatives from most of these houses that, . . . excessive facilities given to foreign bankers, 'either as Open-credits or in anticipation of the sale of States' Securities in this country' were objec- tionable to him and the Company as note issuers.73 They were asked to limit such practices. We do not know the factors causing T. Wiggin and Company to ask the other houses for aid in December but the restrictive policies of the Bank could have contributed to that house's problems. Some of the results of the Bank of England's policies can be seen in Appendix Table B-14. The short-term interest .rate in the London money market rose by almost 52 per cent loetween the second and last quarters of the year. But the 160 value of bills discounted only started to fall in the last quarter. Meanwhile the Bank of England continued to lose Specie. The stringency in the short-term credit market did not seriously affect the long-term credit market, and this was fortunate for the United States, for by the middle of 1836, long-term American debt instruments were being more and more used to refinance Short-term debts as they became payable. American firms faced with the task of covering bills coming due could, instead of remitting foreign exchange or notes drawn on other houses--open credit accounts--remit state and local securities instead.74 The securities were then resold to individual investors. Some Anglo-American houses were also engaged in stock jobbing, that is, the purchasing of blocks of American securities for resale, in smaller units, to individual investors. Short-term credit was important to this operation as it enabled the jobbers to hold the securities until they could be sold, it was hoped, at remunerative prices. The problem in the short- term.credit market probably added to the difficulties which theseehouses faced and were to face in early 1837. The situation on both sides of the Atlantic was omirumls as 1837 dawned. So far, the problems were basically nmnuatary in nature, with some help provided by nature. On the lumerican side, increasing monetary stringency primarily due tx> the fiscal and monetary policies of the Federal 161 government, but aggravated by the difficulties in Texas which cut the inflow of specie from Mexico, were being felt in the monetary centers of New York and Philadelphia.75 Although cotton prices were declining at the end of the year, total revenue was increasing, but it was doubtful how long this could continue. In the United Kingdom, the Bank of England was placing a lid, albeit a bit late in the day, on monetary expansion, and by so doing, tightened the screws on the Anglo-American houses which already faced falling cotton prices. The poor harvests were having their customary ef- fects on the specie supply in England. The future remained uncertain for both countries. The American banking system still had to face the Distribution, while the British were beginning to have difficulties with the joint-stock banks. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER V 1Chaddock, p. 281. 2Niles' National Register, April 23, 1836, p. 126. 3Quoted in Niles' National Register, May 14, 1836, p. 185. Also see Scheiber, Business History Review, Spring, 1966, p. 55. 4The New York City Safety Fund banks were allowed by the state legislature to increase their capital stock through the sale of securities in foreign capital markets. See Henry W. Domett, A History of the Bank of New York, 1784-1884 (New York: 1884), P. 85. 5 Niles' National Register, July 27, 1844, p. 342. 6Stephen A. Caldwell, A Banking History of Louisiana (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1935), p. 54. 7The Financial Register, August 2, 1837, pp. 33-36 reprints the Act in its entirety. 8Scheiber, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 23, p. 2. Gatell, American Historical Review, Vol. LXX, p. 36 lists the increase in the number of deposit banks as from 35 to 96. According to Kinley, p. 82, there were 44 deposit banks as of December 31, 1835 and 91 as of December 31, 1836. 9Even though the relationship between Treasury deposits and bank lending is statistically significant it does not mean that other factors which influence bank portfolio policies were also not important. In line with our conclusions of chapter three it Should be noted that there was no statistically significant relationship between changes in bank Specie holdings and bank lending. 10The Financial Register, August 2, 1837, p. 34. Apparently the government was having difficulty with bank notes of less than five dollars because the Treasury 162 163 notice of April 6, 1835 supposedly banned their use in government transactions by May, 1836. llIbid. Scheiber, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 23, No. 2, p. 206, notes that the deposit banks had to maintain a 25 per cent ratio of specie to note circula- tion. 12See Table 5.8. It should be noted that our Table 5.8 is based on Temin's "Table 4.2." A closer examination of this table and the Appendix Table on which it was based Shows that the aggregate figures are inconsistent with each other. The major factor causing this is the exclusion of the specie holdings of the United States Bank of Pennsylvania prior to 1836. This does not, however, explain all the discrepancies. Note that Temin, in his Appendix Tables A-1 and A-2 lists the Treasury estimate of bank specie holdings as $35 million at the end of 1837, whereas in his Table 4.2 he gives the figure as $31.3 million. Finally, there is no agreement between the Van Fenstermaker estimates given in Table 4.2 and those given in Appendix Table A-1. See Temin, pp. 122, 184, 185, and our Appendix Table B-1. 13See Appendix Table B-3. 14The Financial Register, p. 35. 15Timberlake assumes that intrastate transfers involved no Specie movements but offers no proof. Timber- lake, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXVIII, No. 2. 16United States Senate, Report of the Secretary of the Treasugy, December 26, 24th Congress, 2nd Session, 1836, Senate Document No. 29. 17Senate, Report of the Secretary of the Treasury, 1836, pp. 1, 2. 18 Ibid., p. 3. 19Ibid., p. 4. zorprd., p. 5. It was estimated that less than $2 million had been transferred for this purpose. See p. 6. 21Ibid., p. 22. 22See Appendix Tables B-1, 3. Deposit banks increased their Specie holdings by 122 per cent while all state banks increased their's by 67 per cent but we should not forget that changes in Treasury deposits were paralleled by changes 164 in specie flows for a majority of deposit banks in the last half of 1836. Moreover, as we saw in Table 5.2 specie flows were not related to bank lending activity in any significant way. 23Temin, pp. 128-136. Richard H. Timberlake Jr., "The Specie Circular and Distribution of the Surplus," The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXVIII (April, 1960). 24 Temin, p. 133. 25Temin, p. 134. 26See Table 5.3. Out of the $17.1 million in trans- fer drafts drawn for interstate payment in the last half of 1839, $15.36 was actually paid. 27These figures are for payments actually made. 28Temin, p. 136. 29See Table 5.8. 30As reported in the Financial Register, Vol. 1, p. 14. 31Dewey, Financial History of the United States, p. 228, and Van Deusen, The Jacksonian Era, 1828-1848, pp. 104-105. According to Timberlake the Specie Circular was also intended to reduce the size of the Federal surplus and thus minimize the amount of the distribution. See Timberlake, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. LXXIII (April, 1960), p. 110. 32Arthur H. Cole, "Variations in the Sale of Public Lands, 1816-60," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. IX, 1927, p. 51. 33Smith, pp. 75-76. 34In using the term "Speculator," we are excluding the settlers who purchased land, sometimes by first being squatters, improved it with the expectation of selling it for a higher price in a few years. 35Berry. p. 441. 36In the long-run, the migration from the East to the West also was an important factor. 37Benjamin H. Hibbard, A History of Public Land Policies (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1965), p. 216. 165 38This is the View taken by Temin. See Temin, p. 125. 39Mississippi was the only cotton state where land sales fell during 1836. Cole, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. IX, p. 52. 40Alfred H. Conrad and John R. Meyer, "The Economics of Slavery in the Ante-Bellum South," The Journal of Politi- cal Economy, Vol. LXVI, No. 2 (April, 1958). 41Timberlake, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXVIII, No. 2, p. 111, and Temin, pp. 125-126. 42 Temin, p. 126. 43Ihid., p. 135. 44Ibid., p. 126. 45The United States Bank of Pennsylvania lost about $5.8 million in specie during 1836 but we do not know how much of this went to banks in the land sale states. See Smith, p. 188. 46See Tables 5.8, Appendix Table B-11, and United States Congress, House, 26th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 111. 47Hammond, p. 461. 48The United States Bank of Pennsylvania was still the lending dealer in foreign exchange followed by Alexander Brown and Sons of Baltimore and Prime, Ward and King of New York. See Smith, p. 46. 491n January, 1836, Safety Fund Banks accounted for 77 per cent of all bank lending in the city and 79 per cent of such lending as of January 1, 1837. See Table B-ll, B-l4 in our Appendix. 50See Table B-14. For contemporary and more recent statements supporting the View that specie was withdrawn from city banks, see: Publius (James DePeyster Ogden), Remarks on the Currency of the United States (New York: Wiley and Putnam, 1840), p. 22; Horace Greeley, Recollec- tions of a Buserife (New York: J. B. Ford and Co., 1868), p. 122; Matthews, A Study in Trade Cycle History, p. 16. 51 See Appendix Table B-ll. 166 52These losses cannot be attributed to specie exports. Exchange rates on London did not go to the specie export point until 1837. 53Stuart Bruchey, Cotton and the Growth of the American Economy: 1790-1860 (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, Inc., 1967), p. 229. 54 Ibid., p. 237. 55Smith, Second Bank of the United States, p. 190. 56For reports on monetary pressures in Philadelphia and New York during April and May see Niles' April 16, 1836, p. 114, and May 14, 1836, p. 185. 57Ellis T. Powell, The Evolution of the Money Market, 1385-1915 (New York: August M. Kelley, 1966), p. 310. See also William G. Sumner, A History of American Currency (New York: Henry Holt and Co., 1884), p. 120. 58Clapham, The Bank of England, Vol. 2, p. 150 and Report of the Chamber of Commerce, Manchester, England, December 12, 1839, pp. 304. 59See Appendix Table B-7. Note that interest rates in New York were rising in April and May. 60Arthur D. Gayer, W. W. Rostow, and Ann J. Schwartz, The Growth and Fluctuations of the British Economy, 1790-1850, Vol. 1 (Oxford: Clarendeon Press, 1953), p. 369. It is interesting to note that in both countries, there was some easing of the monetary pressures during the last month or two in 1836. When movements in Short-term interest rates in London were compared with those in New York City, the latter being the dependent variable, the largest R2 obtained was .218. This was when New York interest rates were lagged two months behind those of London. Ibid., p. 272; See also Ryner, University Studies, 61 Vol. 5, No. 2, p. 26. 62Smith, Second Bank of the United States, p. 187. £ = $4.871. 63 Financial Register, Vol. 1, p. 105. 64Smith, Second Bank of the United States, p. 184, and Financial Register, Vol. 1, p. 103. 167 65Ralph Hidy, The House of Baring in American Trade and Finance (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1949), p. 205, and Smith, Second Bank of the United States, pp. 186-187. 66 Hidy, p. 208. 67McGrane, Foreign Bondholders and American State Debt, p. 14. 68 Powell, The Evolution of the Moneerarket, p. 338. 69Thomas Tooke, A History of Prices and the State of the Circulation in 1838 and 1839 (London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green and Longmans, 1840), p. 292; B. R. Mitchell, and Phyllis Deane, Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge: The Cambridge University Press, 1962), p. 488; also see Table 8.1. 70Dealers in the London bill market had been using these bills as collateral for loans from the Bank of Eng- land. See Hidy, p. 205. For Palmer's discussion of the relationship between the Anglo-American houses and the joint-stock banks see W. T. C. King, History of the London Discount Market (London: George Routledge and Sons, Ltd., 1936), p. 945. 71 Buck, p. 157. 72Clapham, Vol. 2, p. 152. 73Clapham, Vol. 2, p. 154. Also see Hidy, p. 208. 74Myers, p. 202. 75Between August, 1836 and January, 1837, New Orleans banks lost $1.5 million in specie, a decrease of approxi- mately 33 per cent. Hunt's (October, 1842), p. 361. The Two deposit banks in that city gained $208,000 between August and the end of December. United States Congress, Senate, 24th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No. 21: pp. 19, 20. CHAPTER VI COTTON, SPECIE AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 1837 The bankers of New York City were at the end of their rope, not to say their specie, by the beginning of May, 1837. During the first nine days of that month, they had to come to the aid of two banks, the Mechanics and the Dry Dock, to prevent them from failing. Facing continued large withdrawals by individual depositors, they decided at a meeting held in the evening of May 9 to suspend the payment of Specie on all their current demand liabilities. This decision was announced on May 10, and by the end Of that day, its effects were being felt in Philadelphia. The bankers of that city, reacting to the action of the New York banks, and fearful of losing specie to the latter if they continued Specie payment, decided to suspend as of May 11. Boston banks followed suit on the twelfth and within a week of the New York suspension, most banks in the United States had suspended.l When we look at the developments which directly led to the panic and suspension, the deterioration of the cotton market and the monetary policies of the Bank of England seem to have been the most important. Both of these were 168 169 interrelated and as we shall see, were in turn, related to such exogenous events as poor grain harvests and the fiscal policies of the American government. Grain, Cotton and the Anglo-American Money Markets The Cotton Market DevelOpments in the cotton market occupied the center stage throughout most of the first five months of 1837. Between January and May of 1837, cotton prices in New Orleans fell by approximately 18 per cent while English prices fell by almost 30 per cent.2 The effects of this were felt not only by those who were directly involved in the cotton trade, but also, by those who were dependent on the cotton growers and shippers, and those who depended on the British textile industry. Suppose instead of the price of cotton fixing itself at a permanently high rate, after a long period of advance, it suddenly and unexpectedly began to decline, and finally sinks, perhaps to half or one- third its former value: we do not see, at once, a cause for widespread ruin, and an immense destruction of private and public credit? You have . . . thrown down the Atlas that upheld the superstructure.3 Through backward and forward linkages, a large segment of the Anglo-American commercial community were to feel the effects of the failing cotton market. The cotton factor was the first to feel the effects of falling cotton prices and it was through him and his position in the cotton trade that shock waves were sent out through the entire commercial world. He purchased or 170 obtained on consignment, cotton which was sold or in turn, consigned to representatives of Northern or Anglo-American houses. Besides his role in the marketing of the main product of the South, the cotton factor also purchased imported and domestic goods from Northern, mainly New York City, merchants, which he then sold to the planters and storekeepers in his region. The factor normally received credit from the New York merchant on terms ranging from six to nine months; in turn, he extended credit, often for longer periods to the planters and storekeepers with whom he dealt. The decline in cotton prices meant that the bills of exchange--cotton bills--which the factor drew when he shipped cotton might be dishonored if the proceeds of the cotton sales could not furnish sufficient funds to pay the bills.4 Without these bills, the cotton factor had no :means of meeting his commitments with the New York merchants nor could the planters receive enough to pay their bills ‘with the factor or local storekeepers. Obviously, local banks would no longer discount notes drawn on the local planters for the factors. In the North, the New York merchants could not (flotain funds to meet their bills due Northern manufacturers (Ir British exporters, who in many cases were the Anglo- ZUmerican houses. The contraction in the flow of remittances fromlthe South not only hurt the Northern merchants, but 171 also, their bankers. The latter found it difficult to get payment on loans and might be asked for extensions of exist- ing loans or undertake new loans to enable the city merchants to meet their commitments. The New York city banks might not, therefore, have been receiving their accustomed inflow of Specie from the South, especially because of the events in Texas. Since Southern banks did not keep large working balances in New York City banks, the latter did not have to fear any signi- ficant loss of Specie to these southern banks. As we shall soon see, the city banks were in a position to lose specie to the banks in the mid-Atlantic states and the mid-West when these banks drew down on their balances in New York. More damaging to the New York city banks than the internal drain caused by the crisis in the cotton market was the external drain caused by the reduction in the supply of cotton bills which were the major source of foreign exchange. Normally, during the last month or two of the year and the first quarter of the next, cotton was being shipped in its greatest volume and the inflow of sterling drafts were concommitantly at their highest levels. This kept exchange rates at their seasonally low levels.5 But the winter of 1836 and the spring of 1837 were not normal for the exchange market. In the first three months of the year (exchange) rates stood at the specie export point and in April they were well above it. Between eight and ten millions 172 of dollars worth of (cotton) bills returned to the United States under protest.6 The foreign exchange needs were met by specie drawn from the banks. It seems that as far as the New York City banks were concerned, this foreign drain appears to have been more important than the internal drain resulting from the disintegrating cotton market.7 So far we have been looking at the consequences of the decline in cotton prices on the banks of New York, but it is important to see what caused the decline in prices as these causes were also to influence the specie position of the city banks. Poor grain harvests in England contributed to a decline in the British demand for raw cotton in two ways. First of all, it led to a decrease in the domestic demand for manufactured cotton goods as more of the income of the working classes had to go for breadstuffs which were higher in price. That is, the increase in the price of bread— stuffs decreased the real income of the British working classes and thereby, decreased the demand for textiles. Secondly, the poor harvests necessitated specie exports to pay for grain imports, these specie outflows leading in part to the tight money policies pursued by the Bank of England. Decline in British demand for raw cotton in combina- tion with an increase in American production produced the sharp break in prices. We can see this in Appendix Table C-4 where American production increased by approximately 173 6.3 per cent during the 1837 crOp year while total British exports of finished cotton goods fell by 13 per cent during the calendar year 1837. Temin has shown in a recent article that the main cause of the price decline, or the reason why it was so severe, lay in conditions on the demand side of the market.8 The failure of some of the leading merchants in Canton China indicates perhaps, that the decline in the demand for textiles was due to more fundamental factors than our information discloses.9 On the other hand, the tight money market in London might have influenced the situation in China, just as it did the Anglo—American trade. The British Money_Markets in the Winter and Spring of 1837 Throughout the last half of 1836 and the first half of 1837, the Bank of England was trying to halt the outflow of specie from its vaults.10 As we saw in the last chapter these losses were mainly due to aid given the joint-stock banks and to pay for grain imports. Grain imports in 1837 were about 51.5 million, this being the largest import since 1831.11 When a central bank of a country which is on the gold standard or some variant thereof, experiences sustained specie losses, it was expected to pursue a deflationary policy characterized by a decrease in the money supply and an increase in the short-term interest rate structure. In the last chapter, we saw that the Bank adopted policies 174 along these lines, although the selective restrictions against the Anglo-American houses and the joint-stock banks were unusual in terms of the adjustment policies supposedly used under the gold standard.12 The short-term market rate of interest stood at five and one-half per cent between November 1836 and April 1837, the bank rate at this time being five per cent. It was only during the second quarter of 1837 that the pressure was strongly felt in the financial markets. Total bank note circulation fell slightly during the second quarter of 1837, but it was only approximately three per cent below its high of the second quarter of 1836.13 More significant as a sign of stringency was the decline in the value of bills of exchange created in England and Wales. This decline amounted to 11.5 million pounds, or a fall of about 15 per cent during the second quarter.14 The British economy soon felt these pressures, Outside the financial mart occurrences reflected and intensified the stress within. Manufacturing in Manchester and Glasgow almost ceased. Unemployment mounted. The volume of bankruptcies moved to its highest figure since the second quarter of 1826 . Particularly Liverpool firms, both importing and exporting, fell by the wayside.15 Bankruptcy fiats recorded in the Annual Register rose from 283 in the last quarter of 1836 to 453 in the first and 520 in the second quarter of 1837.16 Like a giant seesaw, pressure on one side of the Atlantic was to increase the strain on the other side. 175 Because of declining cotton prices and increasing monetary stringency in America, British manufacturers found their American markets drying up. The declining demand for British manufactured goods, especially textiles, both at home and overseas, led to a further decline in the demand for cotton. At the fulcrum of this seesaw were the Anglo-American houses, and they were gradually cracking under the strain. Over- committed in cotton, unable to make payment on cotton bills, they were also unable to pay the firms which sold them the goods for export to America. The situation of the weakest of these firms, the firms known as the 3W's, became generally known to the com- mercial and banking world of England during the last week of February, 1837. As long as they received discountable bills from America, however, they could keep their heads above water.17 Packet arrival dates were days of extreme tension and anxiety; if the ships arrived, it was wondered if any bills were on board; if the remittances came, there still remained the question of acceptance and payment; at once the names on the paper were scanned to ascertain whether or not they were reputable enough for the bills to be acceptable to the Bank of England for discount. Naturally enough, as reports of the mounting tension in the United States came to hand, the directors of the Bank and other men in the money market became still more dubious of bill remittances.l8 The New York Money Market The United States also experienced poor grain har- vests and as in England, they adversely affected the banks as well as the commercial community of the mid-West and New 176 York City. The poor American grain harvests of 1836-1847, "lessened the purchasing power of the farmers and crippled the merchants."19 Just as in the cotton growing regions, growers in the mid-West and Eastern grain regions faced declining incomes and as a result, could not pay off their debts to the local merchants. Most likely they could not buy anything more than the essentials needed to carry them through the next growing season, if they were fortunate enough to obtain credit. The inability of the farmers to pay their debts meant that the country storekeeper could not pay his bills owed to the merchants of the larger interior cities such as Buffalo, Cincinnati, or Pittsburgh. Thus, merchants and their bankers all along the chain of commerce and credit, extending from New York into the interior of the Ohio River Valley found themselves with unpaid bills, defaulted loans, and unsold merchandise in warehouses.20 The banks in New York City were in an especially serious bind. Difficulties eXperienced by interior banks, especially those in the mid-West and New England were trans- mitted to the city banks because of the existence of large 21 Bankers' balances bankers' balances in the city banks. are deposits held in one bank by another for the purposes of financing transactions of the latter or its clients. The growth of this type of deposit in the banks of New York rested upon the basic fact that the volume of goods flowing out of New York towards the interior 177 necessitated an almost constant flow of funds into New York from the interior.22 A bank in Springfield, Ohio might keep balances with a bank in Cincinnati as it knew that its clients dealt with firms in that city and it normally accepted bills or had checks drawn on it which were payable to Cincinnati firms. It might have also kept balances in Cincinnati so that its notes were not returned to it for specie redemption. The Cincinnati bank in turn might have deposits in New York banks for the same reasons. If the volume of trade warranted it, the Springfield bank might directly hold deposits in New York banks. Suppose the Springfield bank needed specie, exchange on New York or city bank notes. It drew on its deposits with the Cincinnati bank which in turn drew on its deposits with New York banks. The drawing down of these bankers' balances in New York could force the city banks to curtail their lending. If this drawing down of bankers' balances was not an isolated event, but part of a general movement, interest rates rose as the supply of funds available to the New York money market decreased. Stock and bond prices could fall as banks asked for payment on call loans--loans payable on demand, normally secured by stocks and or bonds. Since the original deposit might have been loaned by one bank to another and by it in turn to a broker to carry his customer, it is apparent that the demand set in motion by the country banker might have consider— able effect upon the money market.23 178 It was through such a process that a disturbance, a first, affecting banks in the interior, could be trans- mitted to the New York banks. Conversely, the inability of the city banks to meet their demand liabilities, such as occurred when they suspended specie payment in May of 1837, could immediately affect all banks which held such balances in the city. Normally, bankers' balances in the city were drawn down during the fall: It was only during the crop-moving period in the autumn that the direction of the flow was reversed, for country bankers at that time drew against the balances which had been building up during the spring and summer. Deposits of the large import houses of the city increased at this time of the year, as goods were shipped to the interior, thus, to some extent, neutralizing the drain on city banks. In 1836, the New York banks faced more than the normal autumnal problems.25 The import merchants now found it difficult to obtain payment on outstanding debts owed by the interior merchants. The drain on the city banks were thus intensified with the decrease in the inflow of offsetting deposits.. Adding to this was the abnormal withdrawals of bankers' balances as the interior banks attempted to build up their specie hold- ings as well as to meet the demand for exchange on New York required by their customers. Total balances due banks and other corporations, i.e., bankers' balances, fell from $14.3 Inillion in January 1837 to $8.3 million by June.26 179 The New York City banks were losing specie. We previously saw that the reduced supply of cotton bills led to specie exports. The city banks also lost some specie to the interior banks as the latter drew down their balances in the former. Besides these specie losses the city banks, like those in the interior, found themselves with defaulted loans and requests for extensions. These problems were reflected in the movement of short-term interest rates. After easing in January, they rose again in February and continued to rise until the end of April. During this same period Smith and Cole's index of Bank and Insurance stock prices fell from 113 to 97. In Philadelphia the price of Pennsylvania five per cent bonds fell from 101.5 to 97.5.27 So far, all of the difficulties faced by the New York city banks, and to a lesser degree, other banks in the nation were due to the response of the economy to events in the market place. However, the fiscal and monetary poli- cies of the Federal government aggrevated the position of the banks, especially their specie holdings. This came when they could least afford to lose additional specie. It is fruitless to try to blame the suspension of the banks on the Distribution. It is problematical whether any one cause, by itself, could have caused the panic and suspen— sion, but taken together, the economic and non-economic events of late 1836 and early 1837 did have these effects. What we will attempt to do next is estimate the magnitude 180 of the Treasury deposit shifting, necessitated by the Distribution, and if possible, their effect on the specie holdings of the New York Banks. The Distribution and Its Effects on the New York City Banks From Table 6.1 we see that assuming no net revenue inflows during 1837, seventeen out of the twenty-six states had to receive transfers from other states for the distri- bution. The destabilizing effects of these, as well as all interstate, transfers depended not only on their magnitudes, but also on their direction in relation to the normal pat- tern of interstate and interregional payments. Suppose that drafts are drawn on New York City banks, with payment made to banks in Massachusetts. If, at the time that the drafts are payable, New York City banks were net creditors, of Massachusetts banks, the transfers could be made by the use of bankers' balances or bills of exchange, without necessarily causing specie flows. On the other hand, if New York City banks were debtors of the Massachusetts banks, the possibility of specie flows in- creased. It should be recalled that drafts drawn on New York City accounted for slightly more than half of all interstate transfers. While there have been some works which attempted to deal with the effects of the distribution on the banks, most of these are characterized by conceptual and arithmetic .00 .m .00 ucoEdooo mumcmm .c00mmmm pcm .mmmumcou £p00 .mumcmm .mwmumcou moumum Umu0cz .0 .0 .000 .00I05 .mm .00 ucmEsooo mmsom c00mmmm um0 .mmmuocou SD00 .wmsom .mmoumcou mowmum me023 .0 .000 .0 .m .00 ucmEsooo wmsom :00mmwm 0:0 .mmmumcou :u00 .mmso: .mmmuvcou moumum pmu0cs .0 .000 umwoudom .xusmmmue on» 0n mpme muw3 0000 .HmnEwomo mo mu0moamp mzu Eoum 0:00uomuu95m no mc00u0ppm nonuo 0c umnu mmEDmmm 00:90 181 0.00000 0.50050 0.00000 5.00000 0.00000 0.05000 0.00050 0muoa 0.0500I 0.0500I 0.000 I 0.0000 0.0000 0.000 0.000 .5002 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.000 0.000 .xu< 0.0000I 0.0000I 0.0 + 0.0000 0.0000 0.000 0.000 .02 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.00 + 0.00 0.0 0.550 0.500 .000 0.0500I 0.000 I 0.0000+ 0.0000 0.0000 0.000 0.5000 .ch 0.0000I 0.000 I 0.0000+ 0.0000 0.0000 0.5000 0.0500 0050 0.000 I 0.000 + 0.0000+ 0.0000 0.000 0.0000 5.0000 .00 0.000 + 0.0000+ 0.000 I 0.000 0.000 0.0000 5.0000 .ccme 0.0000I 0.0050I 0.0000+ 0.0000 0.0000 0.550 0.500 .00 0.0000I 0.0000I 0.050 + 0.0050 0.0000 0.000 0.000 .mm02 0.005 I 0.000 I 0.000 + 0.5000 5.5000 0.000 0.000 .M0¢ 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.05 I 0.000 0.500 0.0000 0.0000 .mo 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.000 5.000 0.0000 0.0000 .0.0 0.055 + 0.0000+ 0.000 + 5.000 0.000 0.0000 5.0000 .0.2 0.000 + 0.0000+ 0.005 + 5.0000 0.000 0.0000 0.0000 .m> 0J000 I 0.00 + 0.000 + 0.0000 5.5000 0.000 0.0500 .02 5.000 + 0.000 + 0.050 + 0.050 0.0 5.000 0.000 .0mo 0.000 + 0.0000+ 5.00 + 0.0000 0.0000 0.5000 0.0000 .mm 5.000 + 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.000 0.0 5.005 0.0000 .0.z 5.0005I 0.0000I 0.050 I 0.00000 0.00000 0.0000 5.0000 .».z 0.00 + 0.050 + 0.500 + 0.005 0.000 5.005 0.0000 .ccoo 0.00 + 0.000 + 5.500 + 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 .0.0 0.0000I 0.000 I 0.000 + 0.0000 0.5500 0.0000 0.0050 .mmmz 0.000 + 0.005 + 0.000 + 0.000 0.00 0.000 0.000 .u> 0.00 + 0.000 + 0.000 + 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 .m.z 0.000 + 0.005 + 0.050 + 0.500 0.000 0.000 0.0500 6:0mz mpm>0womm mpmuumwmcmue nonsmowo 0000 .00 0000 .00 mumum ucsoe¢IumnEmomo on on Imcnh HmnEmowQ mc30 u0momwo U®>0momm comm ou 0:0uso p0moowo 0mm >00mmw0 mu0moowo 00momme co ucsosd us:0§4 mso DQSOE< co uCDOE< vase ucsoEd £0 mmcmsu co uCDOE< 000000 .0000 .00 @520 00 uo¢ u0mOQmo on» 00 00 Ucm 00 mc00uomm Hmwcs mmumum may >n pm>0oomm can one mucsoe< on» paw .0000 .uwnEmomo 0cm mach 0:0uso mwumum 0muw>mm ocu :0 mu0m0QoQ >uommmua 00 uQSOE¢ onBII.0.0 m00<9 182 errors which make them less useful for our purposes. Bourne's analysis makes use of data which shown gross changes in Treasury deposits and not those due solely to the Distribu- tion.28 Timberlake's analysis contains significant numerical errors besides the implicit assumption that the loss of Treasury deposits involved a sufficient concommitant loss of specie to necessitate a contraction of bank lending activity. As we shall see below, there was no simple rela- tionship between losses of Treasury deposits and specie deposits, at least, insofar as the New York City banks were concerned. Returning to the first mentioned problem with Timberlake's analysis: A total of $2.347 million was drawn on New York City banks for interstate transfer during the Distribution. Of this sum, $300,000 in transfers were dishonored, leaving a net interstate transfer authorized 29 Timberlake, on under the Distribution of $2.047 million. the other hand, estimates the interstate transfers as $1.431 million, the difference, $716,000, amounting to approxi- mately 50 per cent of his original estimate.30 The important point is not the accuracy of our data on Treasury deposits and transfer drafts so much as the validity of the assumption that there is a significant posi— tive relationship between changes in Treasury deposits due to the Distribution and changes in the specie holdings of deposit banks. Furthermore, as we do not have information 183 on the cause of each change in a bank's specie holdings, how do we determine what portion of the change in specie holdings resulting from changes in Treasury deposits was due to the Distribution? As far as this question is con- cerned, there is no solution. We cannot allocate different specie changes to different causes. In Table 5.5 of the last chapter we saw that there was no statistically significant relationship between trans- fer flows necessitated by the first payment of the distribu— tion and changes in bank specie holdings. Yet, on the other hand, we saw in Table 5.2 that a significant relationship did exist between all changes in Treasury deposits and changes in deposit bank specie holdings. What this implies is that changes in Treasury deposits resulting from the Distribution may not have had a major effect on bank specie holdings. The data we have on the Distribution supports the contention of Temin that little specie was transferred as 31 Most of the an immediate result of the Distribution. transfers were made with bank deposit credit or bank notes. But we do not know what then happened with these bank 32 As so much attention in the literature deposits or notes. was focused on the effects of the Distribution on the New York city banks we shall spend some time on these banks. The total amount of money transferred from New York city banks for the first installment of the Distribution was $1.73 million, of which $497,000 was for interstate purposes.33 184 For the second installment which was payable on April 1, transfer drafts were drawn on New York City banks amounting to $1.95 million, of which $770,000 were interstate drafts. Thus, the total transfer drafts drawn on the city banks because of the Distribution, prior to the suspension amounted to $3.68 million, of which interstate drafts, which sup— posedly entailed the greatest danger of specie losses, amount to $1.267 million. When we look at the New York city banks we find little evidence of large interstate specie flows arising directly from the Distribution. Of the nine states which received payment on transfer drafts--those for South Carolina for the third installment of the Distribution were not paid--we have information on the means used to make payment to five of the states. Three of the states, Connecticut, Delaware and North Carolina received all their distribution payments in bank drafts. Vermont received all but $5,000 in bank notes while Tennessee received $80,000 in specie.34 How much of the specie received by Tennessee came from New York city banks we do not know. It seems then that little of the $2.1 million in specie which the city deposit banks lost between December and May was due directly to the Distribution. We have been talking about specie losses directly attributable to the Distribution, for we do not know about the indirect losses. Distribution payments made with bank drafts increased the amount of deposits due to banks outside 185 New York city. Bank notes sent to banks outside the city could increase the debtor position of the city bank vis a vis other banks or decrease its creditor position just as bank drafts did. We have already seen that there was a decline in bankers' balances during this period. We do not know how much of this was due to the exchange of bank drafts arising out of the Distribution for specie. Nor do we know how many bank notes were similarly redeemed. Thus we can never completely know the amount of specie shifting resulting from the Distribution. But should we be so concerned about specie losses arising from the Distribution? We saw in Table 5.2 that the shifting of Treasury deposits had a greater effect on bank lending than did changes in specie holdings. If we are concerned about the effects of Treasury policies on the banks and the money market as well, we must also look at the changes in Treasury deposits. Between December and the beginning of May, the net change in Treasury deposits at city banks was $6.685 million. The Distribution accounted for approximately 55 per cent of total deposit losses. We use net changes as we do not know the intra-monthly changes in Treasury deposits. To what can we attribute the approximately $3 million loss in Treas- ury deposits which were not due to the Distribution? Part of the loss might have been due to the shifting of Treasury deposits necessitated by Section One of the Deposit Act; as 186 of March 1, 1837, the Manhattan Company and the Mechanics Bank had $1.2 million in excess Treasury deposits.35 The payment of the ordinary expenses of the government, espe- cially given the rapid decline in revenue from land sales, probably accounted for some portion of the loss. From what we have just seen it is incorrect to con- clude that the Distribution caused the New York City banks to suspend. All we can say is that the massive shifting of Treasury deposits, of which the Distribution accounted for approximately one-half, weakened the New York City banks. In this position they were not able to meet the demands placed on them in the early weeks of May. Our attention will now turn to the events--which can be characterized as a liquidity crisis--that immediately led to the suspension of the city banks and then the other banks in America. The Suspension of the New York City Banks During the winter and spring of 1837 cotton prices continued to fall and with it went many firms on both sides of the Atlantic which dealt in cotton. The first signifi- cant cotton factor to fail was Herman, Briggs and Company of New Orleans on March 4, 1837; they failed because "they were unable to realize enough from the sale of their cotton to pay the obligations they had incurred in purchasing it."36 The news of the failure reached New York City around March 16, and the New York correspondents of the Southern house, J.L. and S. Josephs and Company, failed as did some of the 187 .000I000 .00 .00 .oz 0£0Esoon mmsom .£00mmmm 000 .mm000£00 £000 .mmsom .mm000£00 mm0m0m 0000£D .5 £50000 .00I0 .00 .00 .oz 0£mEsooo 000£0m .£00mmmm 0£0 .mm000£00 £000 .00M£mm .mm000£00 mm0m0m 0000£D .0 £60000 .00 .m .00 .oz 0£mesooo 000£0m .£00mmmm 0m0 .mmmumcou £000 .000£0m .mmmum£00 m0000m 0000£D .0I0 m£Ed000 "0000500 .0I0 .000 0 .00 0m: .xcmm .moflcmnomz umwoxm m mmzu¢~ 00000 00 mm muuommmo OH Coma .x£mm 00£mnoxm .m0cmnoumz “0 .000 .x£mm 00000mwm0 0000x0 50I00 00050000 00 mm m0nommmn .0£00£:00 00 0000000 00000 0m500 00£ 0020 0000 0000 00000 0050 0000 0000 0000 0050 0£mE00m0m£H zoom .0000& 000 I 00 000 000 000 00 000 000 x£mm .xm m0£msoumz 00 + 050 000 000 000 05 000 05 xcmm 0M£000mz 000 I 000 005 000 000 000 000 000 x£mm £00£D 000 I 000 000 000 050 050 500 500 x£mm .m0£mnoumz 05 I 00 000 00 00 00 00 00 0£mmeou 0000 000 000 I 00 000 000 000 00 00 00 x£mm m.£mEmmvaB 000 I 000 000 000 000 000 000 000 m000500000£m£ 0030000 500 I 000 0000 000 000 000 000 000 x£mm x0£0ocm 000 I 000 000 000 00 00 00 00 0:00 mupmmmumq 050 I 000 000 000 050 00 00 00 x£mm 00m: n0£0>0m 0000 I 0000 0000 005 000 050 000 000 x£mm .m00£msomz 050 I 0000 0000 000 000 000 000 000 0000080 00 x£mm 0000 I can 000m 000, omv 00m 000 000 mamaeoo ampumncmz m00m0000 0002 0.000 000029 039 0 >000 0 00004 0m0 .000 005mmmua :0 00 mm 000 umuflm mHQmwmm manmxmm cam :00 xcmm 00£020 002 m00mommo m0£0E00m0m£0 >000£00 >05m0009 £00300m x£mm zoom 00009 000000m£009 m0£00§4 000000 .£000sn0u0m0o 0:0 00 m0£0E>mm 000:9 0mu0h 030 How mx£mm 0000000 >000 x000 302 8000 000000m£m09 >0£0£ mo 0£50E¢II.0.0 M0049 188 other houses having relations with New Orleans cotton fac- tors. According to Sumner, ninety-eight failures, involving $60.5 million in liabilities took place in New York City between March and the end of the first week of April; in New Orleans, only four or five major cotton factors had been, so far, able to survive.37 On March 23, nineteen days after the first failure of an important cotton house in New Orleans, and most likely before the news spread to Great Britain, the 3 W's applied for and received aid from the Bank of England. The Bank probably granted this aid in order to prevent the failure of many smaller firms in London, Liverpool, and Manchester; not to have granted the aid would have also increased the flow of protested bills to America.38 The news from England as to the conditions of the Anglo-American houses and the attempts of Baring to limit remittances further added to the gloom in New York.39 The failure of the cotton market led to attempts to find some substitute for the discredited cotton bills in the foreign exchange market. . Baring Brothers and Company proposed to the Bank of England that it should open through the Barings a credit of 52,ooo,ooo.40 It was hoped that such aid would ease the pressure in America and facilitate the repayment of the American short-term foreign debt. 189 The United States Bank of Pennsylvania was still the dominent American firm in the foreign exchange market and it was through it that the Bank of England hOped to sustain the western pillar of the Anglo-American trade. On March 22, 1837 the Bank of England sent a letter to Biddle setting forth the terms under which aid would be extended to American merchants and bankers needing foreign exchange. The Bank of England was willing to accept bills drawn on the United States Bank for up to 52,000,000; one half of the bills so drawn to be simultaneously covered by the shipment of bullion to the Bank of England, (it was still losing specie); the other half to be covered by acceptable securities including State securities and bills of exchange. The former were to be redeemed within six months from the maturity of the drafts, the latter would hear five per cent interest per annum payable within a year. At about the same time this letter was being sent to Biddle, he was formulating his own plans which were very different than those envisaged by the Bank of England and Barings.41 Biddle's proposals centered on the use of post- notes--interest bearing notes, payable to the bearer, matur- ing in normally twelve months--which were to be used to obtain exchange on England.42 Basically, Biddle's plan was for the United States Bank of Pennsylvania to issue $5,000,000 in post notes, 190 payable in London or in Paris or Amsterdam. Other important banks in the mid-Atlantic states were also to issue post notes, these banks being the Bank of America, The Manhattan Company, The Morris Canal and Banking Company, and the Girard Bank. As with the United States Bank, the notes were payable in London. The total amount of notes so issued was not fully certain, but estimates ranged between $10,500,000 and $12,000,000.43 Supposedly, these notes were to be supported in the British market by the shipment of £1,000,000 in specie to London, but we have no evidence of such shipments taking place.44 The plan worked, but not for long enough. The post notes, to the chagrin of the Bank of England, were readily accepted by British investors who purchased them from, ”merchant bankers in London who had accepted them as cover 45 Unfortu- for credit to their American correspondent." nately, these notes were not enough to fill the void left by the cotton bills. On April 1, Prime, Ward, and King wrote to the Barings about the condition of the New York City banks: Specie generally is so scarce in the several banks that it can hardly be procurred, indeed individuals cannot well demand it, in our present excited state.46 French banks stopped supplying credit to American firms by the 10th of April and on the 16th, the United States Bank had issued the last of its post notes.47 191 The New York State government also tried to come to the aid of the city banks, but by the time aid arrived, it was too late. The State planned to supply the city banks with $3.5 million in state bonds which the banks could issue. The proceeds of this issue would not be immediately demanded by the state. The loan was on the expressed condition that the Stock of the State, which were then above par in England, should be used as remittances, and to that extent lessen the demand for specie.4 As fate would have it, the enabling legislation was passed on May 9. The commissioners of the Canals also seems to have tried to aid the banks as we know that they offered the Bank of New York on May 4, a loan of $100,000 at five per cent interest to be paid by July, 1837.49 All this aid was not enough. The immediate cause of the suspension was the difficulties with the Mechanics and the Dry Dock banks. On May 4, the city banks went to the aid of the former bank; within a day or two, similar action was taken to support the latter bank. According to a letter written by Gallatin on May 31, 1837, the run by depositors was caused by disclosures of fraud committed on the Mechanics Bank and the Dry Dock Bank. The sudden death of the president of the Mechanics Bank did not help 50 The rest we know, the city the confidence of depositors. banks suspended and others quickly followed. Unlike the bank suspensions of the twentieth century, suspension during this period meant that banks did not close, 192 rather they did not redeem their current demand liabilities for specie.51 In most of the major cities, committees were set up to regulate the banks until they resumed specie pay- ments.52 Domestically, suspension eased not only the plight of the banker but also of those who borrowed from banks. Bankers were now under less pressure to call in loans and might be more willing to renew loans.. Internationally, suspension meant that the gold exchange standard was also suspended. Individuals and firms no longer could obtain gold from American banks to pay foreign debts. Contemporary writers tended to attribute the panic and subsequent suspension to "excessive speculation" although what the term actually meant was never made clear enough. The biases, or shall we say philosophical beliefs of the individual commentator determined in large part, the sources of the excessive speculation. The supporters of the Jackson and Van Buren administrations, in general, blamed the specu— lation on the actions of bankers, land speculators, and merchants. The Whigs, on the other hand, held that the causes lay in the monetary and fiscal policies of the Jacksonians, starting with the "Bank War" and culminating with the Specie Circular and the Deposit Act. In a period where there were strong feelings about tariffs, it is not surprising that some blamed the specula- tion and inflation of 1835-1836 on reductions in the tariff or on the tariff itself. Taussig notes that Calhoun, 193 . . . ascribed the crisis of 1837 to the fact that duties under the Act of 1833 remained too high. The high duties brought in large revenues and caused a surplus in the Treasury; the deposit and distribution of this brought inflation and eventually a crisis.53 When we look at contemporary opinion on the immediate events leading to the suspension, opinion was surprisingly uniform. The blame was apportioned between the failure of the cotton market, the monetary policies of the Bank of England and the pressure placed on the New York City banks due to the Distribution. The opinion of the Bank Commissioners of New York State fairly well summed up what happened. The immediate causes . . . are well known. The simultaneous withdrawing of the large public deposits, and of excessive foreign credits, combined with the great and unexpected fall in the price of the principal articles of our exports with an import of corn and breadstuffs such as had never before occurred, and with the consequent inability of the country, particularly of the southwestern states, to make the usual and expected remittances, did at one and the same time, fall principally and necessarily on the greatest com- mercial emporium of the union.5 Even though we can be fairly certain about what brought on the panic and suspension, are we that clear as to what started the boom in the American economy? It has already been shown that there was no simple causual sequence which brought about the boom. Rather, there was a chain of o developments where the importance of each link cannot be judged independently of the other link. The boom in the Anglo-American cotton market, as Temin shows, was primarily due to rising demand conditions 194 in England, fostered in part by good grain harvests during 55 The absence of any need to pay specie for 1833-1836. imports of grain, enabled the Bank of England to pursue an expansionary monetary policy until the middle of 1836. At about the same time, the monetary policies of the Jackson administration, the Coinage Act of 1834, the removal of the Second Bank of the United States as a "quasi—central bank," and the depositing of Federal funds in state banks, led to a monetary expansion on the western side of the Atlantic. The easy money conditions in London not only enabled the American expansion to continue, even with large balance of trade deficits, but permitted massive inflows of specie into the United States as State and Local governments were able to sell long-term securities in the London and Conti- nental markets. The sale of these securities facilitated a boom in the construction of canals and railroads. A booming Southern economy an expanding mid-Western economy and increasing specialization in the latter and the East provided the demand for goods and services which the banking system ‘was eager to finance. With the collapse of the cotton market and worsening conditions in the London money market, the flow of specie .and credit was reversed. Internal strains added to these (external strains and the American banks led by those in New ‘Yomk City, were forced to suspend. The American economy Ivas in the grip of a liquidity crisis. It was not until 195 late 1839 that a renewed liquidity crisis was also to affect the economy in a more fundamental manner. In the next chapter we will attempt to measure the economic consequences of the Panic of 1837, the attempts made on both sides of the Atlantic to revive the Anglo- American trade, and the eventual failure of these efforts in 1839. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER VI lFritz Redlich, The Molding of American Banking, Part II (New York: Hafner Publishing Co., 1953), p. 259, and the Financial Register, Vol. 2, p. 201, quoting the "United States Gazette" of May 12, 1837. 2See Appendix Table C-5. 3Thomas R. Dew, The Great Question of the Day (Washington: 1840, Thomas Allen), pp. 7-8. See also John C. Brown, A Hundred Years of Merchant Banking (New York: 1909), p. 79. 4Smith, p. 190. If bills were redrawn for lesser amounts, this meant smaller profits or even losses to the cotton factor. Obviously this was preferable to dishonored bills. 5Myers, The New York Money Market, p. 75, and Smith and Cole, Fluctuations in America Business, 1790-1860, p. 78. . 6Smith, Second Bank of the United States, p. 187. 7New York State, Assembly, 6lst Session, Assembly Document No. 71, pp. 4-5. 8Peter Temin, "The Causes of the Cotton Price Fluctuation in the 1830's," Review of Economics and Sta— tistics, Vol. XLIX (November,*1967), p. 469, and Van Deusen, The Jacksonian Era, pp. 116-117. 9 Hidy, p. 221. 10Hidy, pp. 183-184. Also see "Causes of the Present Crisis: Seven Articles," Charleston South Carolina Patriot, 1837. 11B. R. Mitchell and P. Deane, Abstract of British Historical Statistics (Cambridge: University Press, 1962), p. 291. The average price of wheat in England rose from 36 196 197 shillings per quarter in January 1836 to 59 shillings 6 pence per quarter by January 1837. See Niles National Register, October 7, 1843, p. 84. 12 Tilden, Speech of Samuel J. Tilden, p. 3. 13Appendix Table B—12. 14Ibid. 15Hidy, House of Barings, p. 221. 16Norman J. Silberling, "British Prices and Business Cycles, 1779-1850," The Review of Economic Statistics, Vol. V (October, 1923), Supp. 2, p. 252. 17The Barings did everything but publish the names of these houses in an attempt to halt the remittances of bills to these firms as well as to another A.A. house, Lizardi. See Hidy, House of Baring, p. 225. 18Hidy, pp. 220-221. 19Dewey, p. 230. 20Scheiber, Business History Review, Spring, 1966, 21Myers, The New York Money Market, Vol. 1, p. 111. 221bid., p. 103. 23 Myers, Vol. 1, p. 136. 24Ibid. 25 For a discussion of the autumnal pressures on the British money market, see W. Stanley Jevons, "On the Frequent .Autumnal Pressure in the Money Market, and the Action of the .Bank of England," Journal of the Statistical Society of 1London, Vol. 29 (June, 1866), pp. 235-253. 26See Appendix Table B-13. These figures included jbalances due other city banks. In June we know that about 61 per cent of the total was due to banks and corporations outside the city. 27Walter B. Smith and A. H. Cole, Fluctuations in lunerican Business, 1790-1860 (Cambridge: Harvard University ZPress, 1935), p. 174. Hazard's United States Commercial and Eitatistical Register, Vol} 4 (March, 1841), p. 192. 198 28 pp. 80-81. 29United States Congress, House, 25th Congress, lst Session, House Document No. 30, p. 71. 30 Bourne, The History of the Surplus Revenue of 1837, Timberlake, The Journal of Political Economy, p. 116. 31Temin, p. 132. 32Information on the means by which the Distribution was actually shifted can be found in United States Senate, 26th Congress, lst Session, Senate Document, 14. 33United States Congress, House, 25th Congress, lst Session, House Document No. 30, p. 74. 34See source cited in footnote 32, and Appendix Table A-5. 35See Table 6.2 and source cited for column 7. 36Hammond, p. 459, and William G. Sumner, A History of Banking in All The Leading Nations, Vol. 1 (New York: The Journal of Commerce and Commercial Bulletin, 1896), p. 267. 37Sumner, A History of Banking, p. 267, and the "National Gazette,“TApril 22, 1837 cited in the Financial Register, Vol. 1 (October 25, 1837), p. 129. 38Hidy, pp. 220-221 and Clapham, Vol. 2, p. 157. 39Hidy, p. 219. This news most likely reached New “York City during the second or third week of April. 40Hidy, pp. 217-218. 41Hammond, pp. 459-460, and Hidy, pp. 217-218. 42Leland H. Jenks, The Migration of British Capital txa 1875 (New York: 1927), p. 90, and Davis H. Dewey, State Iianking Before the Civil War (Washington: 1910), p. 104. 43Fritz Redlich, "Bank Money in the United States Iering the First Half of the Nineteenth Century," Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 10, No. 3 (January, 1944), pp. 216- 217, and Hammond, p. 463. 44Hammond, p. 463. No information can be found to sfnaw that any specie shipment took place and in fact, Smith 199 and Redlich make no mention of planned shipments. Temin, p. 133 mistakenly assumed that it was only New York City banks that planned to ship specie. 45Ibid. 46Hidy, p. 220. 47Hidy, p. 220. 48Albert Gallatin, Suggestions on the Banks and Currency of the Several United States (New York: Wiley and Putnam, 1841), p. 35. 49H. W. Domett, A History of the Bank of New York, 1784-1884 (New York: 1884), P. 86. 50United States Congress, Senate, 25th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document, No. 365, p. 20. 51 Hammond, p. 478. 52Redlich, Part II, pp. 259-261, details the opera-. tions of committees in several cities. 53Frank W. Taussig, "The Tariff, 1830-1860," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 2 (April, 1888): p. 320, and Patriot, Charleston, South Carolina, p. 2. 54Caldwell, A Banking History of Louisiana, p. 60. See also, "The Constitutional Currency, No. II," National Gazette, April 8, 1837, reprinted in the Financial Register, Vol. 1, September 13, 1837, pp. 84-85, and Publius, Remarks on the Currency of the United States, p. 19. 55 Temin, Review of Economic and Statistics, pp. 463- 470. CHAPTER VII THE AFTERMATH OF THE PANIC: DISLOCATION AND RECOVERY Even as the news of the suspension of the East Coast banks spread into the interior and eastward across the Atlantic, moves were already afoot to revive the prostrated cotton market and financial community. Though there would be heated controversy over the methods used-~the necessity and timing of resumption, the role of the United States Bank and others in cotton speculation-~there was little doubt that something would be done. With a revitalized banking and mercantile credit system and a stabilized cotton market, many believed that the boom times of the mid-1830's would return. In this chapter we shall first attempt to deter- mine the economic damage resulting from the deflation and financial panic of 1837 and then see how the economy was able to recover almost entirely by the end of 1838. Dislocation and its Economic Costs If we divided the economy into three sectors, agri- culture, commerce, and construction, we find that of the latter two (excluding urgan construction which was to drop sharply in 1837 and the following years) commercial activity showed the most signs of being adversely affected by the panic. 200 201 As we saw in the last chapter agriculture was gener- ally depressed in the latter half of 1836 and throughout 1837. In the South this was due to conditions mainly on the demand side of the cotton market while in the grain growing areas, poor crops depressed farm incomes. Without any information on the number of farm foreclosures or the rate of farm tenancy we cannot determine the extent of dislocation in the agricultural sector. A problem common to all three sectors of the economy was the lack of money and credit. In more modern terms this is called a lack of liquidity. This not only inhibited trade and production but also made it more difficult for farmers, merchants and manufacturers to pay maturing obligations. Many manufacturing companies throughout New England and the Central States failed not entirely because their business was unprofitable, but because they could not, in default of currency, realize upon their assets to meet immediate obligations.l ' Merchants might have had warehouses filled with domestic and imported goods. They would be wary of selling them to Western and Southern merchants who could offer only bank notes and bills of exchange which were often totally unaccepted or ac- cepted only at large discounts. During the last half of 1837 bank notes on Southern and Western banks either were not .accepted or discounted at rates ranging from five to fifteen jper cent, while discounts on domestic bills of exchange were fica pnm>umr "wmpHHnEmuv Homanooma moumum poses: or» CH mwoeum huHOOEEOU macmwaorz .oHoO .m ussuus .mIs .Hoo .oss .ssa .mms .mms .oo .lmmms .umoum suuuum>sso oum>umm homomussmoc owmalomna .mmocflmsm cmowumfid CH mcoflucsuusHm .OHOO .r unruu< pcm tuflfim .m umuawz “HHIOH .mIH .HOU ”mmousom .mmoflum OHMmmHorzm o.maI o.omI o.osI o.oHI o.mmI o.H~I o.oHI o.s I o.mHI o.omI o.m~I .oooIsoum mmma o.oaI o.H~I o.omI o.m I m.NHI o.mHI o.o I o.m I o.oHI o.oHI o.oHI .oomItoum omoa H.m + m.v + m.m + o.m I H.~ I m.o I o.H I m.HHI o.m I N.~ I o.HHI .suoI.ooo m.m + m.s + o.oHI o.v I o.m I ~.s I m.m I o.s + m.m I H.m I o.m I .oooI.>oz o m.o I o.oHI o ~.o I m.m I o.H + m.m I s.m I m.o I m.H I .>oZI.uoo ~.o I o.s I o.HH+ o.oaI o s.~ I o. I s.m I o.m I o.H I o.s I .uooI.uoom o.m I o.m I o.oHI o o m.m I o. I m. I o m.H I m. + .uoomI.os< o.~ I m.m I o.oHI s. + H.m I o.H I o. I m.H I o.H I m. I o.m I .oosIsHoo o.m I o.o I o.HHI H.N I o m.H I m.s I o.m I s.m I o m.m I saoqusso o.H + ~.o I s. I m.a I o.s I m. I m.H I s.H I s.H I m.H I o ossoIsmz o.H + ~.m + s.s I H.~ + o.H + m.H I a. I m.~ I o.m I s.~ I m. I ssz.uom o o m.m + v.H + m.m + o o. + m. + m. I s.m I o.m I .ussI.umz s.H I o.o I o.s + o o.H I s.m I a. I m. I m. I m. + o.m I .usz.som o.H I v.o + o.v + m.m I m.~ + o o s.H + o.m + m.m + m.m + .oomI.suo xmch xmch mammauo .CCwU mcmmHuo sou .maflrd .U.w.z mmOOAHm umOOAMm xooum momma 3oz mmoflum 3oz Immaumru mooflud moowum mmmOHum >uAUOEEOU auHUOEEOU moan x00um mmoflhm mamw OHmm mmoflum mamm warm wuHOOEEOU Hmeuu Hangs uHsmcH noon couuoo OHOSZ IOHOLB warm Ioaorz IOHOLZ acumcww Imsch IHSOHHO¢ s xsmm Iauom Iososz .mmma hatucos .mwflumm OOAHm mmumum ponds: pmuomamm cw mmmcmnu wmmucmoummln.m.m mqmoz m b.@ mmmH .woo muummSSUmemz m.m n.m ova .cmo m.m s.m mmma .cmb mnflo xno» zmz m.H n.v mmmH .oma H.m m.m mmma .cmn UnmamH moocm m.m m.v mmmfi .>oz n.H m.m mmma .uoo m.H m.m mmma .omQ mammano 3oz o.m m.m mmmH .>oz m.m o.m mmma mash m.m m.m mmma .cmn magmampmenm mflommm mflommm on op mmHuHHHQMflA muHmome panama mumo mxcmm pcmEma ucmnnsu .mmma mxcmm omuomamm ca mmcwpaom mflommm xcmm on wpwmommo ocmEmo paw mmHuHHHQMHA pcmEmQ ucmnuso mo moflummln.v.m mqmOZV.HH .Ho> .mcflwmmwz m.pcm:oumz ammonsom .cOOHHHE N.vmm mHmB evma ca wmonu mHH£3 .sOHHHHE H.Hmw mm3 mvma Hmomflm ca mpnomfifl Umpmsflpmsb .mvma 0» HOHHQ Umms Ham» Hmomflm nucofi m>am3u mnw Op vema cam mvma mpmsmpm mummm Hmomflm ucmumsou .vvma .om wssolmvma .H mHSb Scum mm3 wwma Hmomflw maflc3 mva .om made-mwma .H Hmnouoo Scum mmz Hmmm Hmomflw mvma map .mflzp mo mmsmomn .om muse-H wash Op 323 cm .pmmmIH .poo poflumm mzu Eonm pmmsmno mm3 Hmmm Hmomwm map .mvma sHm Hm m.m> vva mm o.mv mva mm m.ow mvma om v.m> vaH Hm 5.0m ova mm m.mm mmma on «.mw mmmH mm m.vm bmma mm n.5HH mmmH mm n.nm mmma mm n.Hh vmma em m.mm mmmH mummy Hmowflm pmumsmpmsa chum» Hmomwm .mpHOdEH mmHMpm pmpHCD Hmuoe cu ucmpmcoo Hmmw muHOQEH xuom 3mz mo oflumm Aooo.ooowv .OOOH-mme .xuow 3mz Ho wuom wry owcH manomsH-.N.O mHmae 324 financing this trade on the London and Continental money markets. As a consequence of the crippling effects in the United States of the long depression, a larger pro- portion of the flow of merchandise to America after 1842 was on British or European account.66 It is impossible, given the available information, to determine how much of the decline in imports was attri- butable to the new tariff legislation. As we noted in our discussion dealing with the decline in imports in 1840, we do not know the composition of imports. Further adding to our data problems is the change in fiscal years during 1843. What information we do have indicates that there may have been some import substitution in the iron industry but little if any in the cotton textile industry. Iron imports during 1843 were about 25 per cent of their 1842 level. Taking into account the difference in fiscal years, this still represents a considerable decline. Domestic production, on the other hand, rose substantially indicating 67 American cotton that import substitution did take place. textile production concentrated mainly on areas which were not in direct price competition with British textile im— ports.68 Since domestic production was estimated to have fallen by about two per cent during 1843 the decline in demand, both for domestic and textiles appears to have come from falling incomes and a contracting supply of money and credit.69 325 So far we have looked at the balance of trade surplus from the import side, but what about exports? Exports in 1843 were $17 million less than in 1842. How much of this decline was due to the shorter fiscal year? Lacking a complete breakdown of exports by calander year we cannot answer this question with any accuracy. We do know that cotton exports rose by $1.5 million while exports _—.‘-‘- I from New York City fell by only $70,000 during the year.70 Improved harvests in Great Britain led to decreased Ameri- can grain exports, wheat and flour exports fell by about 71 $4.25 million. It appears then that some of the decline in exports was due to the change in fiscal years. In addition to the specie inflows resulting from the trade surplus, there appears to have been some capital inflows resulting from the continuing drop in interest rates in Great Britain. The Merchant's Magazine reported at mid-year that British investors were sending funds to New York City in an attempt to invest in mortgages at a hoped for six per cent return.72 Specie inflows thus were the result of a large balance of payments surplus arising from a sharp drop in imports due to the poor state of the American economy and a lack of short-term credits from abroad which inhibited imports. There also appears to have been some inflow of long-term capital, especially during the last half of the year. 326 What was the relationship between these massive specie imports and the recovery in the American economy? Most of the specie imports appears to have flowed into the banking system. What induced the bankers to again lend money to merchants, manufactures, planters and farmers? We have already seen that by the middle of 1843 funds were going into the financial markets raising security prices and lowering rates of return. Eventually as the return on government securities--Federal as well as state and local-— fell, bankers started to look to commercial loans as a source of higher earnings. But why should merchants, manu- factures and others again begin to borrow from the banks? An answer to this question appears if we look at the "neo- Keynesian" eXplanation of the factors causing an upturn in the business cycle.73 As the economy moves toward the low point in a busi- ness cycle merchants and manufactures, facing declining sales and the unavailability of credit drew on their inven— tories rather than reorder or expand production in order to meet the low levels of demand facing them. Eventually inventories would be so depleted that in order to meet the existing demand, reordering and then production would increase. This upturn in demand can coincide with an upturn in gross investments as replacement investments might no longer be postponable. According to McGouldrick's estimates gross investment in plant and equipment by New England 327 textile mills increased from $20,000 in fiscal 1843 to $409,000 in fiscal 1844.74 The increasing liquidity in the economy, due not only to the effects of the specie inflows but also perhaps to the liquidation of debts during 1842 and 1843, coming at a time when demand for consumer goods and investment good was picking up, helped to turn the economy upward. This upturn in demand generated by inventory and capital replacement needs took place at a time when the stabilization of agricultural prices and the late summer harvests gave added reason for merchants and manufactures to expand their ordering and production schedules. Bankers and merchants throughout the chain of commerce and credit from the manufacturer and importer to the final consumer felt renewed confidence and ability in extending new credit. The combined effects of renewed demand and increased liqui- dity and stability in the financial system meant the end of the 1839—1843 recession and the gradual recovery of the American economy. By the end of 1843 agricultural incomes began to expand, although the full effect of this was not felt until 1844. The rising prices and the prospect which this gave of increasing farm incomes and demand, revived trade. With this in mind the merchants began to come to the Eastern mercantile centers to rebuild their stocks of goods. They were aided in this as bankers, having watched their specie 9; v d 328 holdings increase, began to extend credit, first to those buying financial instruments and then, in the last months of the year to the merchants all along the channels of trade. The prospect of renewed agricultural demand, both in the North and in the South fueled the fires of recovery while an expanding money and credit based resulting from near record specie inflows, stoked the fires of recovery. P-fi‘mn The 1839-1843 Recession in Historical Perspective Having examined the 1839-1843 recession we shall conclude this chapter by comparing this recession first with that of the 1930's and then with other ante-bellum economic disturbances. Peter Temin has made a thorough comparison of 1839- 1843 with the 1930's. He concluded that while the monetary effects of the former disturbance were greater than that of the later one, because of the assumed flexibility of prices, real output did not decrease but actually increased during 1839-1843.75 This perhaps surprising conclusion depends on the confidence which one places on the available aggregate out- put estimates and the base years used. Temin comments on one of the problems in using the aggregate estimates which were derived from the work of Gallman. The author of these estimates of G.N.P. . . . in the 1840's emphasized that the annual data were derived only 'to reduce our dependence on benchmark 329 year estimates.‘ They were not intended to be used for analyses of yearly changes. . . . If they are to reduce our dependence on benchmark year estimates . . . they must also reflect the conditions of the economy in the intervening years.76 Moreover, two components of output were excluded from these estimates, value added by home manufactures and changes in 77 Could their exclusion significantly over- inventories. state or understate changes in G.N.P. during 1839-1843? This would depend on: 1. the ability of households to shift from the consumption of manufactured goods to goods produced either at home or locally and obtained through barter; 2. the relationship of inventories to total sales; 3. the relative size of these two components to G.N.P. in 1839 and 1843. As incomes fell and with the contraction of money and credit, households shifted from the purchase of manu- factured goods to those produced at home or locally and obtained by barter. If this led to an increase in the ratio of home manufactured goods to market manufactured goods, then output in 1843 would be understated. The only information available which might throw some light on the magnitude of home manufactures are the estimates of West- ward shipments on the New York Canals. These shipments fell in 1840 and 1842 and the tonnage in 1843 was only about one per cent above the level of 1839. Shipments to states and territories west of New York also fell in 1840 330 and 1842 and the 1843 tonnage was 15 per cent below that of 1839.78 If we accept this information as representative of what actually happened throughout the economy we could then conclude that the ratio of household manufactures to manufactured goods was higher in 1843 than in 1839. The estimate of G.N.P. in 1843 thus are understated by excluding this component of total output. A decrease in inventories reduces gross private domestic investment and thus the magnitude of G.N.P. Was the ratio of inventories to total production and sales at a lower level in 1843 than in 1839? We have no quantitative means of determining this. But it seems likely that with declining demand and contracting credit, merchants and manufactures might have drawn down their inventories rather than make commitments for new goods or raw materials. To the extent that this happened the G.N.P. estimates are overstated in 1843. Given the methods used to derive the G.N.P. estimates for these years the errors introduced by the omission of these two components do not appear to sub- stantially alter Gallman's estimates. A more serious pro- blem, however, arises from the years chosen. We have seen in this chapter that there was a tem- porary revival in economic activity during 1841. The question obviously arised is how much of the estimated increase in G.N.P. in the 1839-1843 period actually took place in 1841. The G.N.P. data does not throw light on 331 this, but by looking at the textile industry we can readily see the problem involved. According to Temin, Two estimates of the cotton-textile industry's have been made recently. They differ on many counts, including the method of derivation, but they both fail to show a sustained decline in production in the early 1840's. In fact the production in 1843 was shown to be about 15 per cent above the 1839 level in both estimates.7 The estimates Temin refers to are those of Davis and Stettler which have been published in a National Bureau study and that of Zevin which is not yet available.80 A closer look at the Davis and Stettler data shows that while textile output did increase by 15 per cent, 81 If this is almost all of this was concentrated in 1841. also true for other sectors of the economy, and the data on internal trade tend to support this, then much of the growth in output during the 1839-1843 period took place in 1841. Growth rates may still have been positive in 1842 and 1843, but at much smaller levels than Temin indicates. The paucity of data is not the only stumbling block in any attempt to compare the 1839-1843 period with that of the 1930's, for what we are attempting to do in this case is to compare two different economies. The American economy was not the same in these two periods and the differences were not just simply that of size but also of structure. Using Gallman's estimates, not for yearly changes but for interdecade changes, we see that the share of output attri- buted to agriculture fell from 72 per cent in 1839 to 56 per 332 cent in 1859 and 33 per cent by 1899. In 1929-1933, agri- culture accounted for slightly less than 10 per cent of output. The 1840 Census estimated that about 11 per cent of the pOpulation lived in urban centers with population of 2,500 or more, while in the 1930 Census the figure was 56 per cent.82 Thus, if we want to gauge the relative magnitude of the 1839-1843 recession it is more appropriate to compare it to other ante-bellum economic disturbances. A Comparison of Ante—Bellum Economic Disturbances The data available for a comparison of the three major ante-bellum economic disturbances; 1818-1822, 1837- 1843, and 1857-1860, will be found in Table 9.3. There are many similarities between these three periods.83 All were characterized by domestic banking problems leading to suspension as well as by international monetary disturbances. In the first period the international mone- tary picture was disturbed by the attempts of the European powers to return to specie payment following the Nepoleonic Wars. In the second period there were the specie losses of the Bank of England arising from poor harvests and monetary problems on the Continent, especially in France and Belgium. Finally, in the last period the attempt of the French government to rebuild its specie holdings caused a con- traction in the British capital markets which in turn affected the railroad speculation then going on in the United States. 333 TABLE 9.3.—rComparison of Three Ante-Bellum Economic Dis- turbances, 1818—1822, 1837-1843, 1857-1860. Percentage Changes Series 1818- 1837- 1839- 1857- 1822 1843 1843 1860 Warren & Pearson Wholesale Price Index (1830 = 100) -31 -35 -33 -20 Export Price Index (1830 = 100) -48 -47 -51 -16 Import Price Index (1830 = 100) -30 -24 -19 -06 Western States Terms of Trade (1824-26 = 100) -31 -27 -29 -04 Money Supply -05 -43 -27 -18 Number of Banks n.g. -17 -23 +04 Bank Lending (Total loans) n.g. -45 -43 -15 Current Demand Liabilitiesa n.g. -48 -40 -22 Imports -57 -67 -73 —24 Exports -41 -26 -26 -07 Land Sales Acreage -81 -91 -78 -87 Cotton Prices (New Orleans) -62 -63 -54 -13 aGross figures, includes inter-bank holdings. n.g. ~ not given. Sources: Rows 1-4, 9-10 Douglas C. North, The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860 (New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1966), pp. 240, 242, 255, 233, 234. Row 5, Source cited in Appendix Table B-7, Col. E. Rows 6—8, 11, The Statistical History of the United States Fram_' Colonial Times to the Present (Conn.: Fairfield Publishers, Inc., 1965), pp. 624-625, 239. Row 12, Source cited Appendix Table C-5, Series A. 334 Agricultural overproduction in the United States also characterized all three periods, cotton in the first two and grains in the last one and to some extent in the middle period. The first two periods were also character- ized by international price deflations. The recessions of 1818-1822 and 1837-1843 were fairly similar, at least in terms of the fluctuations in the series given in Table 9.3, though according to Berry the West, the area up to the Ohio Valley, appears to have been worse off in 1821 than in 1842.84 In general it appears that the latter recession was more severe than the former. An economy with most of its labor force in agriculture and with few urban centers-- according to the 1820 Census only about 7.2 per cent of the total population lived in urban centers--wou1d be less affected by economic disturbances, as contrasted to natural disturbances such as poor crops, then a relatively more industrialized economy.85 It would be easier for a small labor force not fully committed to the work place to move back to the farm during hard times and for farmers to in- crease the amount of home manufacturing they undertake as the market for their cash crops declines. This does not mean that there would not be serious problems, especially for those regions which were mainly involved in plantation agriculture such as cotton, sugar and rice, or in manu- facturing and commerce, but rather that there would be 335 relatively less real hardship involved. In this light it may be assumed that for the country as a whole, the reces- sion period of 1837—1843 involved more economic hardship than the earlier recession period. From the information we have on internal as well as external trade in the 1830's it seems safe to assume that there was unemployment. We have, however, no informa— tion on its relative seriousness in the manufacturing and trade centers of the East coast and South and perhaps those of the interior, such as Cincinnati and Pittsburgh, as well. The lack of any significant body of contemporary comment about unemployment in the 1840-1843 period indicates that the problem, at least to the commentators, was not serious. Price flexibility, the ability of some of the unemployed workers to switch to agricultural occupations, though not necessarily through a westward migration, mini- mized the declines in output and unemployment that did take place during the 1837-1843 recession.86 The End of the 1839-1843 Recession, an Overview Through the early 1840's the American economy at- tempted to recover from the after effects of the panic's of 1837 and 1839. This was almost accomplished in late 1840 and early 1841 but the recovery could not be sustained in the face of falling prices and renewed monetary problems 336 highlighted by the failure of the United States Bank in February 1841. The situation was worsened by the end of the internal construction boom. States became discouraged over the fail- ure of many of these projects to provide the financial benefits claimed for them. It became clear that ordinary tax revenues would have to be used to pay the interest pay- ments on the bonds issued for these projects, this helped to dampen the fervor for continuing them. The London and Continental capital markets reacting in part to the financial difficulties of the various state governments, some of whom missed interest payments and repudiate their obligations in part or total, closed their doors for the time being to American securities. Contracting trade and concommitantly a contracting money and credit base brought the economy to its low point in 1842 and early 1843. But the fall in demand, prices, and money, led to a large balance of trade surplus which, with better crOps in Great Britain and increased Conti- nental supplies of specie enabled near record amounts of specie to flow into the United States. Sustained recovery came in late 1843 and 1844 as the crops of the South and the West went to market and the banks and the entire finan- cial community again felt confident enough to extend credit to the agricultural, mercantile and manufacturing interests of the country. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER IX lMcGouldrick, pp. 29, 142. Davis and Stettler estimated that output rose by less than one-half per cent during calander 1840. Davis and Stettler, Output, Employ: ment and Productivity in the United States After 1800, p. 221. 2Fred M. Jones, Middlemen in the Domestic Trade of the United States 1800-1860 (Illinois Studies in the Social Science, Vol. 21, No. 3, Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1937), p. 70. 3See Appendix Table B-6. 4In 1840 an estimated $7 million in United States Treasury notes were issued. These notes were interest paying post—notes and can be considered to have been part of the money supply and thus the decline in the money supply would be overstated as these estimates excluded Treasury notes. Peter Temin, The Jacksonian Economy (New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1969), p. 192; Niles' National Register, April 24, 1841, p. 28. 5The Independent Treasury Act was passed on July 4, 1840. As there was little contemporary comment on the sub-treasuries withdrawing money, especially specie, from circulation, it is likely that the main recipient of the public's specie was the banks. See Myers 1, pp. 180-181. 6North, Economic Growth, p. 243; Warren and Pearson, p. 12. 7In 1837, imports fell by $47 million or 26 per cent. See Appendix Table A-1. 8North, Economic Growth, p. 243. 9Louis B. Schmidt, "The Internal Grain Trade of the United States," Iowa Journal of History and Politics, Vol. 8, No. 1 (January, 1920), pp. 42, 44, 45; North, Economic Growth, p. 243. 337 338 10Niles National Register, July 4, 1840. llNiles National Register, June 27, 1840, p. 257; Appendix Table C-3. 12Matthew B. Hammond, The Cotton Industry (American Economic Association Publications, New Series, No. 1; New York: Macmillan 1897), p. 118; Appendix Tables C-3 and C-5. 13 Albion, p. 411. l4Niles National Register, April 18, 1840, p. 98; For a similar statement about the London money market in late June see Niles' National Register, July 25, 1840, p. 321. 15Niles National Register, July 25, 1840, p. 322; May 23, 1840, p. 178. l6Niles National Register, July 25, 1840, p. 321; December 26, 1840, p. 257. l7Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 7, November 1840, p. 456. According to Caroline Ware the election of Harrison buoyed the spirits of manufactures as they believed he would be for a higher tariff and the restoration of a national bank. C. Ware, p. 105. 18Bank and Insurance Index included only New York City firms, the Railroad index included those of Massachu- setts, New York, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Maryland. See Smith and Cole, pp. 175-176. 19 See Appendix Table C-5. 20Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 7, October, 1840, p. 361. Also see comments of Smith on the financial situation in New Orleans and Mobile in the Spring of 1840. Smith, p. 221. 21Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 11, November 1844, p. 452. 22Jones, p. 70. $21 of the $25 million increase in imports came from Europe, $13 from Great Britain and $8 million from France. Statistical History of the United States, p. 553. Victor Clark implies that at least part of these imports resulted from British and Continental manufactures dumping goods on the American market. Clark, p. 249. 23Albion, p. 411. 339 24McGouldrick, pp. 142, 159. 5Domestic financing was most important in the railroads of New England. See Alfred D. Chandler Jr., "Patterns of Railroad Finance, 1830-1850," Business History Review, Vol. 28 (Sept. 1954), and Taylor, pp. 98-99. 26Hidy, pp. 289-290; Smith, p. 221-222. 27Smith, p. 222. For a discussion of the Canadian- American border difficulties which also helped to depress the London bond market see Samuel Eliot Morison, The Oxford History of the American People (New York: Oxford University Press, 1964), p. 66. 28Fishlow, pp. 385, 399; Fogel has the peak in the consumption of rails in 1841, Robert W. Fogel, Railroads and American Economic Growth (Baltimore: John Hopkins Press, 1964), p. 174. 29H. Jerome Cranmer, "Canal Investment, 1815-1860," Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, ed. William N. Parker (New York: National Bureau of Eco- nomic Research Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 24, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960), pp. 555-556; Comment of Harvey H. Segal, pp. 565-566. 30Rezneck, American Historical Review, LX, p. 680. For those states which used DistrIbutIon funds in this manner see Bourne, pp. 122-123. States which had difficulty in meeting interest payments as well as those which defaulted are discussed in B.U. Ratchford, American State Debts (Durham: Duke University Press, 1941), pp. 97-107 and Benjamin R. Curtis, "Debts of the States," North American Review, Vol. 58 (1844), pp. 132-134. 31 Statistical History of the United States, p. 115. 32For a discussion of the aid given by New York and Boston banks and other financial firms to the United States Bank and the other banks of Philadelphia see Smith, pp. 225-226; Niles National Register, January 30, 1841, p. 352; and Redlich, II, p. 272. 33For some of the reasons behind the failure of the United States Bank see Smith, pp. 60, 226; and Niles Na- tional Register, February 13, 1841, p. 372. 34Berry, p. 463. 340 35Niles National Register, March 13, 1841, p. 32. On April 17, the National Register carried news that the Mich- igan State Legislature had passed a law limiting fore- closures. Niles National Register, April, 17, 1841, p. 105. 36Niles National Register, June 19, 1841, p. 252; September 25, 1841, pp. 52, 64; October 30, 1841, p. 129. Gayer, Rostow and Schwartz reported that at the end of the year, both Britain's home and foreign markets were depressed. Gayer, Rostow, Schwartz, I, p. 283. 37The National Register reported that there was a shipment of $1.1 million in specie from New York City to Great Britain and the Continent during one week in late September. Niles National Register, October 9, 1841, p. 96. ' 38North, p. 236. 39There are some problems in the use of the bank specie data for 1841. According to Smith the United States Bank during the month of January lost $6 million in specie of which $4 million was due to the redemption of bank notes. Furthermore the reports of aggregate bank specie holdings as of the end of 1841 and the beginning of 1842 appear not to have included Ohio banks, which, at the end of 1840 held a reported $1.2 million in specie. On both accounts then, the losses of specie by banks appears to have been overstated. See Smith, p. 226; Berry pp. 588- 589. 4OSilberling, The Review of Economic Statistics, V, Supp. 2, p. 252. Mitchell and Deane, p. 271; Williamson, p. 285; Appendix Table B-5. 41Redlich, II, p. 272; Niles National Register, April 2, 1842, p. 80. 42Niles National Register, June 18, 1842, p. 256; James, p. 143; Hammond, Banks and Politics, p. 612; Sta- tistical History of the United States, p. 624. 43J. Van Fenstermaker, The Development of American Commercial Banking: 1782-1837 (Kent, Ohio: Kent Uni- versity, Bureau of Economic and Business Research, 1965), pp. 66-67; Elliot, p. 983. 44Elliot, pp. 988-999, 1017. Treasury notes accounted for $11.4 million of this borrowing. Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 6, May, 1842, p. 478. 45See Table 7.1. The National Register carried comments on this in July. Niles National Register, July 2, 1842, p. 288. 341 46Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 6, May, 1842, p. 482. 47McGouldrick, pp. 33, 159-160. 48Moses Abramovitz, "Long Swings in American Eco- nomic Growth," in New Views on American Economic Develop- ment, ed. Ralph Andreano (Cambridge, Mass: Schenkman Publishing Co., 1965). . 49There is a confusing picture in grain prices. Wheat prices at Baltimore fell from $1.25 in May-June to 88 cents by the end of the year. Niles National Register, August 17, 1844, p. 399. Schmidt shows a rise in average prices of wheat from 95 cents in 1841 to $1.12 in 1842. Schmidt, Iowa Journal of History and Politics, Vol. 8, p. 45. Finally, the price of wheat at Albany, New York fell between January 1842 and January 1843. New York States, Assembly, 69th Session, Senate Document 92, pp. 25-27. Prior to the 1840's most of the mid-western grains were shipped via New Orleans. See Morton Rothstein, "Ante- bellum Wheat and Cotton Exports: A Contrast in Marketing Organization and Economic Development," Agricultural History, Vol. XL, No. 2 (1966), p. 95. 50 North, p. 253; Albrion, p. 411. 51Paul B. Trescott, "Federal-State Financial Rela- tions," Journal of Economic History, Vol. 15, No. 3 (Septem- ber 1955), p. 242; Ratchford, pp. 107, 110-112. 52 Hidy, pp. 294, 302-303. 53See Appendix Tables A—1 and B-5. 54Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 7, December 1842, p. 553; Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization, 1606-1865, II (London: George G. Harrap and Co. Ltd., 1957), p. 750. Note the comment about the lack of money in the interior. 55Frank W. Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States, 8th Rev. ed. (New York: Capricorn Books, 1964), Chapter 3; V. Clark Stressed the psychological boost of the new tariff legislation, especially in its role of removing uncertainty as to what the new schedule would be. V. Clark, p. 205. 56According to Clark Warburton as long as the Bank of England's discount rate was five per cent or more, it would be able to attract specie from other countries or at least reduce its losses. In April, 1842 the Bank lowered 342 its discount rate to four per cent from the previous five per cent, this together with increased Russian gold produc- tion enabled both American and British banks to simultane- ously increase their gold holdings. Clark Warburton, "Monetary Disturbances and Business Fluctuations in Two Centuries of American History," In Search of a Monetary Constitution, ed. Leland B. Yeager (Cambridge: Harvard UnIversity Press, 1962), pp. 73-74. 57The Barings began to expand their activities during the summer of 1842, Hidy, p. 311. 58 59Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 8, March, 1843, p. 273; Estimates of specie imports found in Niles National Register, July 15, 1843, p. 307. 6ONiles National Register, April 8, 1843, p. 83; Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 8, June 1843, p. 558; Appendix Table B-7, and Smith and Cole, p. 174. 61 Niles National Register, August 26, 1843, p. 416. 62See Comments in Niles National Register, September 14, 1843; Merchant's Magazine, Vol. 9, October 1843, p. 272; and December 1843, p. 561. 63Most monetary interpretations of this period, such as Temin's appear to assume an instantaneous response of economic activity to changes in the monetary base-- mainly specie in the banks--and in the money supply. In part this is due to the necessity of working with annual data, but as we have seen, this oversimplifies the rela- tionship between money and economic activity. For the present day state of knowledge on the size and time path of the lag between money and economic activity see the article by Cagan and Gandolfi and the comments by Davis and Tucker in the April, 1969 American Economic Review. Phillip Cagen and Arthur Candolfi, "The Lag in Monetary Policy as Implied by the Time Pattern of Monetary Effects on Interest Rates," American Economic Review, LIX, No. 2 (May, 1969). 64 North, p. 236. 651bid., pp. 219, 220. 66Hidy, p. 356. 67Frank W. Taussig, "Statistics of Iron and Cotton, 1830-1860," Quarterly Journal of Economics, II (April, 343 1888), p. 379; and Taussig, The Tariff History of the United States, p. 126; Domestic production estimates are found in TauSSig, Quarterly Journal of Economics, II, p. 380; and Rovert W. Fogel, Railroads and American Economic Growth (Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press, 1964), p. 132. 68 McGouldrick, p. 31. 69Davis and Stettler, Output, Employment and Pro- ductivity in the United States After 1800, p. 221. 7OAppendix Table C-2 and Niles National Register, January 27, 1844, p. 344. 71Schmidt, Iowa Journal of History and Politics, V01. 18’ p. 430 ' 72Niles National Register, July 8, 1843, p. 304. British capital exports rose from a £600,000 in 1842 to + 59.3 million in 1843, though a large part of this outflow was destined for the Continent and not the United States. On this latter point see A. G. Kinwood, "Railway Invest- ment in Britain, 1825-1875," Economics, New Series, Vol. XXXII, No. 127 (August, 1965), p. 320; for British capital eXports see Williamson, p. 280. 73The following is based on Robert Gordon's analysis of the factors causing economic recovery from the low point in a business cycle; Robert A. Gordon, Business Fluctua- tions, 2nd ed. (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1961), pp. 302-312. . 74 McGouldrick, p. 164. 75Temin, pp. 155-165, especially pp. 156-157. 76Ibid., p. 157. 77Gallman, Output, Employment, and Production in the United States After 1800, pp. 26, 61, 62. 78 Albion, p. 411. 79Temin, p. 161. 80David and Stetler, Output, Employment and Produc- tivity in the United States After 1800; Robert B. Zevin, The Growth of Cotton Textile Production After 1815, forthcoming. 81 Davis and Stettler, p. 221. 344 82Robert E. Gallman, Trends in the American Economy_ in the Nineteenth Century, p. 26; Statistical History_of the United States, p. 14. 83The following discussion is based on North, pp. 182-188, 212-214; Smith, pp. 108-110. 84 Berry, p. 468. 85Statistical History of the United States, p. 14. 86The "Safety Valve Tyeory," supposedly does not apply to the United States after the late 1830's, yet what did happen to the workers made unemployed by the ending of the canal and railroad projects. We can find no contempo- rary comment on the disposition of these workers during the early 1840's, only for 1837 and 1839 do we find comments about them and then only in cities such as New York. For a discussion of the Safety Valve Theory see F. A. Shannon, "A Post Mortem on the Labor Safety-Valve Theory," Agricul- tural History, Vol. 29 (January, 1945). CHAPTER X CONCLUSIONS During the mid-1830's and early 1840's the United States economy went through a period of economic prosperity and recession. This movement in economic activity and growth was brought about by economic and non-economic forces Operating on both sides of the Atlantic. In this work I have attempted to show how important components in the structure of the American economy; the economic rela- tionship between America and Great Britain and the mechanics of international monetary relations enabled economic dis- turbances on one side of the Atlantic to be transmitted to the other side, and in the process multiplying the magni- tude of the disturbances. The structural elements were the cotton industry and the banking and financial system. Both the American and British economies being connected through the cotton and credit markets and the specie flow mechanism. Excess Demand and Economic Growth America during this period had both an excess demand for goods and services and an excess demand for money-- specie coins, bank notes, demand deposits--with both being financed by an excess supply of securities.1 The demand was 345 346 excess in terms of domestic production at the full employ- ment level of output. It was generated by the incomes produced by the rapid growth of cotton and grain production and by the expansion in gross domestic investment mainly due to the boom in internal improvement projects such as canals and railroads. This excess demand meant not only rising prices but also balance of trade deficits between fiscal 1831-1837 inclusively. Concommitant with the excess demand for goods and services was an excess demand for money generated by the growth in output and demand as well as by the continuing specialization of production taking place in the economy. This excess demand for money was reflected in different ways, economic and political. Between fiscal 1832 and 1837 inclusively, while the United States had trade deficits it also had net specie imports. The excess demand allowed the rapid expansion of banks and current demand liabilities and it was here that the political problems arose. There were conflicting political pressures as the growing demand for money came face to face with the "hard money" beliefs of important figures in the Jackson adminis- tration led by Jackson himself. Thus we had the so-called Bank War. The formation of the Deposit banks was a response, however unconscious, to meet the demand for banks and banking facilities. At the state level the Free Banking Laws en- acted in the last years of the 1830's facilitated the growth il ll Il‘lll’1,. - 347 of banks and bank money creation as the case of Michigan shows. But at the same time the Federal government as well as some state governments attempted to limit the use of bank notes. Finally, prices of goods and services could rise with the excess demand, and the United States could import specie because American securities found a ready market in Great Britain and the Continent.2 Throughout this period, short—term credit instruments were important not only in America's domestic trade but also in its foreign trade. According to North's balance of payments estimates, United States aggregate indebtedness to foreigners rose from $89 million in fiscal 1331 to $297.2 million by the end of fiscal 1839. The volume of capital imports between 1830 and 1839 was sizable. Relative to the size of the economy it was probably the most significant inflow of capital during the nineteenth century. The excess demand for goods and services, the excess demand for money, and the sale of securities strongly suggest that economic growth in the United States depended on the growth and health of the British economy. A Summer of the 1833-1843 Period The 1834-1836 Boom A boom in the market for raw.cotton developed during the mid-1830's. British demand for raw cotton expanded rapidly to meet the needs of a growing textile industry 348 serving home and foreign markets. Good grain harvests in the British Isles stimulated demand for British textiles and other goods. They meant lower food prices and an increasing real income for the British working population, therefore an increased demand for textiles and other manu- factured goods. Finally, good harvests meant that large grain imports were not needed so that specie outflows would be minimized. The Bank of England was able to maintain its bullion holdings at levels that allowed expansionary mone- tary policies. ‘ Expanding credit aided by the discounting practices of the newly important joint-stock banks, especially those dealing in the Anglo—American trade, and the lenient poli- cies of the Bank of England facilitated the expansion of British domestic and foreign trade. Easy credit in the short-term capital markets spilled over into the London capital market which absorbed large amounts of American securities. British credit was vital for the expanding world trade in general. As American money and credit is used to supplement gold in international trade today, so in the nineteenth century Great Britain's money and credit was used to supplement the inadequate supply of gold and silver to finance international trade. On the Western side of the Atlantic the boom in the cotton market came at a time when the American supply 349 was expanding. The United States became the major source of supply of raw cotton to the British and Continental textile industries. At the same time the American banking and credit system also grew rapidly, fed by the growing volume of specie inflows and the bills of exchange arising out of the cotton trade. The Bank War facilitated this expansion. The re- moval of the Second Bank of the United States as a possible controller over the note issues of the state banks was not as important as the shifting of Federal deposits to the newly created deposit banks; banks which as we have seen, did pursue a generally more expansionary lending policy than non-deposit banks. Concommitant with the expansion of the cotton trade and the banking and financial system was a desire at the state and local level to emulate the success obtained by the State of New York and New York City from the Erie Canal. This emulation led to a great eXpansion in internal improvements as East coast centers such as Baltimore, Boston, and Philadelphia attempted to build canals and railroads to compete with the Erie Canal which was fun- nelling the trade of the west in increasing amounts to New York City. In the interior Ohio and Michigan and other states were building canals to connect their states via the Great Lakes to the Erie Canal and other East-West transportation 350 lines then being built. The South had some interest in internal improvements but most of the efforts were on the founding of banks which would finance the development of new cotton lands. From the West, South, Mid-Atlantic and to a much lesser degree the New England States, securities flowed across the Atlantic to the capital markets of Great Britain and the Continent. The Second Bank of the United States-- which would become the United States Bank of Pennsylvania in 1836--became the main intermediary between the issuing state and local authorities and the foreign capital mar- kets. As domestic goods and labor were the largest component cf’ cost for internal improvements, the main purpose of the foreign capital inflow was the supplying of foreign exchange or specie to maintain or expand domestic currency. Much of the specie was used to satisfy the public's demand for gold and silver thus minimizing the drain on bank specie holdings.4 By the end of 1835 the United States was in the midst of a boom from the timber of Maine to building in New York City and the Pennsylvania, New Jersey and Maryland canals. Further South the boom encompassed the cotton lands of the lower Mississippi Valley. In the West it encompassed the growth of new cities, the construction of canals and the eXpanding cultivation of new grain lands. 351 The boom was financed by an unusual assortment of domestic and foreign bankers, capitalists and merchants. There was an amalgam of the new money of New York, the South and the joint-stock banks of Great Britain with the old money of Boston, Philadelphia and London. The con- servative banking practices of Boston and London contrasted with those of the cotton banks in the South and the joint— stock banks of the industrial areas of Great Britain. Governmental bodies in the United States and Great Britain ~generally had little control over bankers besides the latters own conceptions of proper and prudent banking. How banks were regulated was still being worked out by a trial and error process. The mercantile credit systems on both sides of the Atlantic were in similar straits. There were old line mercantile houses such as Brown Brothers and the Barings and newer firms in the Anglo-American trade such as Humphreys and Biddle. The scramble for the expanding American trade caused many British firms to loosen their credit policies. The same loosening occurred in the domes- tic American trade as the lines of credit stretched further and further from the importer or manufacturer to the final consumer. Thus the potential was being stored up for a larger and larger reaction once the credit chain was broken. 352 The Panic of 1837 The bubble was pricked, and not just once. In the United States in late 1836 and early 1837 a series of natural and political events destabilized the American economy and made it highly vulnerable to shocks from Great Britain. The American grain crops were poor in 1836, necessitating grain imports in the East while farm incomes were falling because of ruined crops, in the interior. Eastern merchants and their bankers now found bills of ' exchange returning from the interior unpaid. At the same time the Eastern bankers were under pressure from the South and Great Britain as well as from the monetary and fiscal policies of the Federal Government. Cotton prices fell as British demand slackened. As in America, the grain crops in the British Isles were poor, but the consequences were much more serious. British home demand for textiles fell as rising food prices decreased the purchasing power of the working population and as the money and credit supply began to undergo severe strain. These strains in the money markets would culminate in failures among the joint-stock banks and the Anglo-American mercantile houses. The Bank of England found its bullion holdings declining as more and more grain had to be im- ported and as it extended aid to the hard-pressed joint- stock banks of England and Ireland. Eventually, the Bank of England implemented a contractionary monetary policy 353 with special attention on the Anglo-American houses and the joint—stock banks. With the clamps being placed on the money and credit supply, the situation became more bleak for British mer- chants and manufacturers, for credit was vital to domestic and foreign trade. One place where this contraction was most felt was the market for raw cotton. It could not be sustained in the face of declining demand and contracting credit facilities. With the continuing fall in cotton prices more unpaid bills of exchange flowed across the Atlantic. A declining supply of cotton bills in the American foreign exchange market, together with rising short-term interest rates in London, combined to raise the exchange rate on London to the specie export point. The Eastern banks, especially those in New York City, found themselves losing specie as merchants drew down their deposits to obtain specie to ship to creditors in Great Britain and the Continent. Even before this was taking place, the Federal government's fiscal and monetary policies increased the pressure on the New York and other East coast banks and shook public confidence in banks in general. The various Federal laws designed to remove bank notes from circula— tion, culminating in the Specie Circular, increased the pressure on banks, especially those in the West. The 354 Specie Circular was not as crucial to the Eastern banks as was the handling of the Federal surplusses. The sections of the Deposit Act dealing with the distribution of the Federal surplus caused large movements in Federal deposits at deposit banks in New York City and elsewhere. Nowhere was this more untimely than in New York City. The city banks lost a great prOportion of their Federal deposits during the last half of 1836 and the first few months of 1837. Large depositors watched these losses with increasing anxiety. They felt confident in the banks only so long as they believed that the banks could redeem their deposit liabilities and their bank notes in specie. Continued specie losses due to the shifting of Federal deposits and specie exports added to an already worsening financial situation. The supply of money and credit contracted as banks in New York City and other commercial centers curtailed their lending activities as bills came from the interior, and the South unpaid. The inflow of British short-term credit temporarily dried up as the Bank of England tightened the pressure on the Anglo-American houses and as bills of exchange drawn on British firms returned to American unpaid. In Early May, 1837, the crisis turned into a panic in New York City when depositors started runs, first on a few banks which were in difficulty and then on all city banks. On May 10, 1837, the New York City banks suspended 355 specie payments, and as news of this spread throughout the country the other banks in America followed suit. The boom bubble had been pricked. As in 1929, many speculators found that paper profits had turned into real losses. Farmers and planters found themselves with debts that could not be repaid until grain harvests improved and cot- ton prices rose. Merchants and manufacturers found them- selves over-supplied with goods but.under-supplied with money, credit or customers. There was unemployment in New York and other cities, but the preponderant role of agriculture and the apparent flexibility of prices dissipated much of the unemployment and dislocation by the middle of 1838. People in the cities had difficulties in making it through the fall and winter of 1837. It is difficult to judge the actual extent of the dislocation for with the exception of New York City, for which information on the size of the relief rolls is avail- able, other quantitative information is 1acking. The worst of the economic hardships, however, appears to have passed by the spring of 1838. The Recovery and the Panic of 1839 By the end of 1838 the American economy was in the midst of a recovery. The resumption of specie payments during 1838, the upturn in the cotton market, improvement in the grain trade, and the continuing inflow of British long-term capital helped to bring about the recovery. 356 However, the recovery could not be sustained. There had been no significant changes in the structural factors which made the American economy highly vulnerable to economic disturbances from the cotton and money markets of Great Britain and the United States. There was nothing on the horizon to justify expectations of continuing recovery. Rather, there were signs that the recovery would end. Adverse conditions in Great Britain and the Continent would soon make themselves felt in the cotton and money markets of America and Britain. It became apparent by the late summer of 1838 that the grain crops in the British Isles would be exceptionally poor. At the same time, a monetary crisis and recession developed in France and Belgium. Taken together these develOpments dampened the home.and Continental demand for British manufactured goods while at the same time increasing the outflow of Specie from Great Britain. By the late spring of 1839 the recovery in America, dependent as it was on the health of the British economy, appears to have run out of momentum. Cotton prices were falling again and banks in most sections of the United States, perhaps mindful of their problems in 1837, began to curtail their lending activities. During the summer lyrices fell across the country, and as in 1837, this meant 'unpaid bills of exchange to merchants and bankers. Falling gnzices, unpaid bills of exchange, a contracting supply of 357 credit and money and increasing exports of specie to Great Britain brought on another financial crisis. Caught in the middle was the United States Bank of Pennsylvania, overcommitted in cotton and state securities at a time when the British markets were contracting. It was losing specie to other domestic banks as well as to its foreign creditors. The United States Bank suspended in October and soon afterwards many other banks in the nation, excluding those of New York and most of New England, also suspended or failed. These suspensions marked the end of the boom of the 1830's and the beginning of a depression which, except for a slight recovery during 1841, lasted until early 1844. The 1840-1843 Depression Unlike the suspension of 1837, that of 1839 did not bring with it any relief to the economy. Prices, especially industrial, fell sharply during the remainder of the year and into the middle of 1840. The boom in the construction of canals and railroads came to an end in 1840. The inflow of foreign long-term capital slowed to a trickle when the British grain crops once again were poor, further contract- ing the inflow of foreign capital, while the disorganized American banking system made it difficult to obtain funds to continue construction. There was a temporary halt to the decline in economic activity in the last months of 1840 and through most of 1841. 358 This was due mainly to an upturn in agricultural prices, especially cotton, causing demand, which had been relatively dormant during 1840 to increase. Merchants rebuilt their inventories and this led to increased domestic production and expanded imports. But with the continuing decline in the construction of canals and railroads, intensified in February 1841 by the failure of the United States Bank, and the worsening economic situation in Britain, the outlook again became poor. Cotton prices fell and the expanding imports of 1841 had to be paid in specie. The American economy again sank into a depression which continued until a low point was reached in early 1843. Recovery finally came to the United States in 1844 in an almost textbook fashion. A record trade surplus resulting from low levels of domestic demand and the revival of the British economy due to better grain harvests led to massive specie imports. The increased liquidity of the banks and the financial community in general and the stabi- lization of cotton and other agricultural prices led to a renewed demand for manufactured goods. This stimulated the rebuilding of depleted inventories. Added to these increases in demand was an upturn in gross investment as accumulated replacement needs began to be met. The sum total of all this was an upturn in aggregate demand which was widespread enough to turn the economy around and start it on the road to recovery. 359 Concluding Comments The boom in the American economy during the 1830's could continue only as long as aggregate demand continued to increase. It was fed by the growing cotton trade, expand- ing investments in internal improvements, and increasing economic specialization as reflected in the growth of the textile industry and the breaking of new grain lands in the west. But this growth in aggregate demand which outstripped domestic production could be maintained only as long as overall equilibrium in the commodity, money and security markets was maintained. Thus, because there was excess demand for goods large balance of trade deficits developed. These deficits might have led to Specie outflows, a con- tracting supply of money and credit therefore at least slowing down the rate of growth of demand and output. America was fortunate for easy money conditions in Great Britain during the 1830's facilitated specie inflows. Directly specie inflows were facilitated by American export of short— and long-term debt instruments to British and Continental firms which supplied credit to American import- ers and foreign capitalists who purchased American securi- ties. Indirectly it was when British short-term credit instruments--later supplemented by those issued by the United States Bank, which in turn obtained credit in Britain and France--were substituted for Mexican silver and other specie in the China trade. These capital flows enabled the 360 United States to retain a greater portion of the specie inflows. The sale of long-term securities in Britain and the Continent enabled the builders of canals and railroads in America to obtain imported machinery, but more importantly foreign exchange. The foreign exchange could be sold for-- or specie could be directly obtained and used for--domestic currency needed to pay the day to day construction costs of these projects. The securities were also used to refinance a portion of the country's short—term debts as they matured. The excess supply of American securities--excess in terms of the American market--flowed into the foreign capital markets, of which the British was the largest, and enabled the United States to finance much of its infra-structure construction as well as its trade deficits. British capital and cotton markets were crucial to the American economic boom of the 1830's. The financial crises of 1837 and 1839 and the economic downturns which followed resulted fundamentally from the adverse conditions of these markets arising from poor grain harvests and financial disturbances. In 1837 the financial disturbances centered in the joint-stock banks of Great Britain and Ireland while in 1839 they centered in banking disturbances in France and Belgium. In both years domestic problems made the American economy more receptive to the shocks emanating from the eastern side of the Atlantic. 361 The pattern of boom and bust, growth and stagnation in American during the 1830's and early 1840's did not result from any single source. It cannot be explained solely in terms of the actions of the Jackson and Van Buren administrations as many of the earlier writers have done. Neither can it be eXplained as Temin did mainly in terms of changes in the supply of money and credit as the banking and financial sector of the economy adjusted to the changing inflows and outflows of specie. Finally this pattern of economic activity cannot be explained as the result of the growth in the cotton market and the concom- mitant increase in economic specialization which took place. Rather movements in the American economy were due to cir- cumstances on both sides of the Atlantic. If America did not have an almost monopolistic position in the world cotton market, and if the British grain crops had been uniformly poor through the 1830's; the British cotton and capital markets would not have been able to purchase American cotton and securities to the extent that they did. American eco- nomic growth in the 1830's depended on a healthy British economy, just as Europe's in the late 1940's and early 1950's did on that of the American economy. FOOTNOTES CHAPTER X lCopper coins in the denominations of cents and half-cents were minted but in terms of value were minor in comparison to the total money supply. 2Estimated total state debts rose from $25.6 million in 1830 to approximately $174 million by the end of 1838. See Table 4.1 for sources. 3Douglass C. North, "The United States Balance of Payments, 1790-1860," Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, p. 585, and Table on p. 581. 4We can think of individuals as holding a portfolio of money assets consisting of bank notes, demand deposits and specie. Between these components there will be some desired ratio determined by such factors as income, availa- bility of banking services, confidence in banks, and the types of payments which have to be made. During the 1830- 1834 period Temin has estimated that the proportion of money held as specie was about one-half the average level of holdings during the 1820's. The massive specie inflows of 1834-1836 made it easier for the public to increase their specie holdings. We should also remember that in times of uncertainty over the safety of paper money, people have tended to increase their holdings of gold and other precious metals. The best current example of this was the French public's movement into gold coins during the currency pro- blems of the late 1960's. 362 BIBLIOGRAPHY 363 BIBLIOGRAPHY Abramovitz, Moses. "Long Swings in American Economic Growth." New Views on American Economic Develop- ment. Edited by Ralph Andreano. Cambridge Mass: Schenkman Publishing Co., 1965. Adams, Charles F. Further Reflections Upon the State of the Currency in the United States. Boston: William D. Tickman, 1837. Albion, Robert G. The Rise of the New York Port. New York: Charles Schribner's and Sons, 1939. Albion, Robert G. Square Riggers on Schedule: The New York Sailing Packets to England. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1938. Ames, E. "Trends and Cycles and Stagnation in United States Manufacturing Since 1860." Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 11. October, 1959. Andreades, A. History of the Bank of England. London: P. S. King and Son, 1909. Andreano, Ralph, ed. New Views on American Economic Develop- ment. Cambridge, Mass: Schenkman Publishing Co., I965. Appleton, Nathan. Remarks on Banking and Currency. 2nd ed. Boston: Little and Brown, 1841. Bascom, John. "American International Indebtedness." Yale Review, Vol. 9. November, 1900. Berry, Thomas S. Western Prices Before 1861. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1943. Bigelow, Erastus B. The Tariff Question. Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1862. Bourne, Edward G. The History of the Surplus Revenue of 1837. New York: G. P. Putnam's Sons, 1885. Bolles, Albert S. The Financial History of the United States. 3rd ed. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1891. 364 365 Boyle, J. E. Cotton and the New Orleans Cotton Exchange. Garden City, New York: 1934. Brothers, Thomas. The United States of North America as They Are. London: Longman, 1840. Brown, John C. A Hundred Years of Merchant Banking. New York: 1909. Bruchey, Stuart, ed. Cotton and the Growth of the American Economy, 1790-1860. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, Inc., 1967. Bruchey, Stuart. The Roots of AmericopEconomic Growth. New York: Harper and Row, 1965. Buck, Norman. The Development of the Organization of Anglo- American Trade, 1800-1850. New Haven: Yale Uni- versity Press, 1925. Cagan, Phillip, and Gandolfi, Arthur. "The Lag in Monetary Policy as Implied by the Time Pattern of Monetary Effects on Interest Rates." The American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings, Vol. LIX, No. 2, May, 1969. Caldwell, Stephen A. A Banking History of Louisiana. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1935. Callender, Guy S. The Economic History of the United States, 1765-1860. Boston: Ginn and Company, 1909. Chaddock, Robert E. The Safety Fund Banking System in New York, 1829-1866. Washington: National Monetary Commission, 1910. Chandler, Alfred D. Jr. "Patterns of American Railroad Finance, 1830-1850." Business History Review, Vol. 28, September, 1954. Clapham, John M. The Economic Development of France and Germany, 1815-1914. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- versity Press, 1929. Clapham, John M. The Bank of England. 2 Vol. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1944. Clark, John G. The Grain Trade in the Old Northwest. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1966. 366 Clark, Victor 8. History of Manufacturing in the United States, 1607-1860. Washington: Carnegie Institu- tion of Washington, 1916. Cole, Arthur H. Wholesale Commodity Prices in the United States, 1700-1861. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1938. Cole, Arthur H. "Variations in the Sale of Public Lands." Review of Economic Statistics, Vol. IX, No. 1, January, 1927. Cole, Arthur H. "Evolution of the Foreign Exchange Market of the United States." Journal of Economic and Business History, Vol. 1, No. 3, May, 1929. Cole, Arthur H. "Seasonal Variations in Sterling Exchange." Journal of Economic and Business History, Vol. II, No. 1, November, 1929. Cole, Arthur H., and Frickey, Edwin. "The Course of Stock Prices, 1825-1866." The Review of Economic Sta- tistics, Vol. 10, No. 3, August, 1928. Colton, Calvin. Public Economy For the United States. New York: A. S. Barnes and Co., 1849. Coman, Katharine. The Industrial History of the United States. New York: Macmillan, 1913. Commercial Review of the South and the West. Edited by J.D.B. DeBow. 'Vol. 4, No. 1, September, 1847. Conant, Charles A. A History of Modern Banks of Issue. 5th ed. New York: G. P. Putnam and Sons, 1915. Conrad, Alfred H., and Meyer, John R. "The Economics of Slavery in the Ante-Bellum South." The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. LXVI, No. 2, April, 1958. Conard, Alfred H., et a1. "Slavery as an Obstacle to Economic Growth in the United States: A Panel Discussion." The Journal of Economic‘History. Vol. 27, No. 4, December, 1967. Cooney, E. W. "Long Waves in Building in the British Economy of the Nineteenth Century." Economic History Review. Vol. 13, December, 1960. Cranmer, H. Jerome. "Canal Investment, 1815-1860." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. 367 Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 24, National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960. Curtis, Benjamin R. "Debts of the States." North American Review. Vol. 58, 1844. Danson, J. T. "Investigation of the Changes in the Condi- tion of the PeOple From the Harvest of 1834 to the Harvest of 1847." Journal of the Statistical Society. Vol. XI, 1848. Davis, Lance E., and Hughes, Jonathan R. T. "A Dollar- Sterling Exchange, 1803-1895." The Economic History Review. Vol. 13, No. 1, August, 1960. Davis, Lance E., and Stettler, H. Louis, III. "The New England Textile Industry, 1825—1860: Trends and Fluctuations." Output, Employment, and Productivity in the United States After 1800. Studies in Income and Wealth No. 30, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1966. Depew, Chauncey M., ed. One Hundred Years of American Commerce. New York: D. O. Hayes and Co., New York, 1895. Dew, Thomas R. The Great Opestion of the Day. Washington: Thomas Allen, 1840. Dewey, David R. Financial History of the United States. 12th ed. New York: Longman, Green and Company, 1939. Dewey, David R. State Banking_Before the Civil War. Wash- ington: National Monetary Commission, 1910. Dillistin, William H. Bank Note Reporters and Counterfeit Detectors, 1826-1866. New York: American Numis- matIc Society, 1949. Dixon, Frank Haigh. A Traffic History of the Mississippi River System. Washington: National Waterways Commission, Doc. No. 11, 1909. Domett, H. W. A History of the Bank of New York, 1784- 1884. New York: 1884. Dorfman, Joseph. The Economic Mind in American Civiliza- ' tion, 1606-1865. 2 Vol. London: George G. Harrap and Company Ltd., 1947. 368 Duane, William J. Narrative and Correspondence Concerning the Removal of the Deposits and Occurrences Con- nected Therewith. Philadelphia, 1838. Eckfeldt, Jacob B., and Dubois, William E. A Manual of Gold and Silver Coins. Philadelphia: Assay Office of the Mint, 1842. Elliott, Jonathan. The Funding System of the United States and of Great Britain. Washington: Blair and Rives, 1845. Ellison, Thomas. The Cotton Trade of Great Britain. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1968. Ellsworth, Paul T., and Leith, J. Clark. The International Economy. 4th ed. New York: The Macmillan Co., 1969. Ely, Richard T. Taxation in American States and Cities. New York: 1888. Entz, John F. Exchange and Cotton Trade Between England and the United States. Charleston: 1840. Evans, David M. The History of the Commercial Crisis of 1857-1858. London: 1859. Evans, George H. Jr. Business Incorporations in the United States, 1800-1943. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1948. Evans, Michael K. Macroeconomic Activity: Theory, Fore- casting and Control. New York: Harper and Row, 1969. Financial Register of the United States. Philadelphia: Adam Waldie, 1838. Ferber, Robert, and Verdoorn, P. J. Research Methods In Economics and Business. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1962. Fishlow, Albert. American Railroads and the Transformation of the Ante-Bellum Economy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965. Flint, Charles L. et. a1. One Hundred Years of Progress of the United States. Hartford: L. Stebbins, 1871. 369 Fogel, Robert W. Railroads and American Economic Growth. Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press, 1964. Ford, A. G. "Capital Exports and the Growth of Argentina, 1880-1914." The Economic Journal. Vol. LXVII, September, 1958. Frickey, E. Economic Fluctuations in the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1942. Friedman, Milton. "Monetary Data and National Income Estimates." Economic Development and Cultural Change. Vol. 9, No. 3, April, 1961. Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna J. The Great Contrac- tion. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965. Gallman, Robert E. "Commodity Output, 1839-1899." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 24, National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960. Gallman, Robert E. "Gross National Product in the United States, 1834-1909." Output, Employment, and Pro- ductivity in the United States After 1800. Studies in Income and Wealth, No. 30, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1966. Gallatin, Albert. Suggestions on the Banks and Currency of the Several United States. New York: Wiley and Putnam, 1841. Gatell, Frank O. "Spoils of the Bank War: Political Bias in the Selection of Pet Banks." American Historical Review. Vol. LXX, No. 1, October, 1964. Gatell, Frank 0. "Secretary Taney and the Baltimore Pets: A Study in Banking and Politics." Business History Review. Vol. 39, 1965. Gatell, Frank O. The Jacksonians and the Money Powers, 1829-1840. The Berkeley Series in American HiStory, Chicago: Rand McNally and Co., 1967. Gayer, Arthur D.; Rostow, Walt W.; and Schwartz, Anna J. The Growth and Fluctuation of the British Economyi» 1790-1860. 2 Vol. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1953. 370 Goodrich, Carter. Government Promotion of American Canals and Railroads, 1800-1890. New York: Columbia University Press, 1960. Gordon, Robert A. Business Fluctuations. 2nd ed. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1961. Gouge, William M. An Inquiry Into the Expediency of Dis- pensing With Bank Agency and Bank Paper in the Fiscal Concerns of the United States. Philadelphia: William Stavely, 1837. Govan, Thomas P. Nicholas Biddle, Nationalist and Public Banker, 1786-1844. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959. Gray, Lewis, C. History of Argiculture in the Southern United States to 1860. Vol. 2. Washington: Carnegie Institution, 1933. Greef, A. O. The Commercial Paper Houses in the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1938. Greeley, Horace. Recollections of a Busy Life. New York: J. B. Ford and Co., 1868. Hammond, Bray. Banks and Politics in America From the Revolution to the Civil War. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957. Hammond, M. B. "The Cotton Industry." American Economic Association Publications, New Series No. 1. New York: Macmillan, 1897. Hansen, A. H. "Wholesale Prices, 1801-1840." American Statistical Association Journal. September, 1924. Havens, R. Murray. "Reactions of the Federal Government to the 1837-1843 Depression." The Southern Eco- nomic Journal. Vol. 8, No. 3, January, 1942. Hazard's United States Commercial and Statistical Register. Philadelphia: William F. Geddes. Hazard, Blanche E. "The Organization of the Boot and Shoe Industry in Massachusetts Before 1875." The Quarteriy Journal of Economics. Vol. 27, February 1913. Hedges, Joseph E. Commercial Banking and the Stock Market Before 1863. The John Hopkins.UniversIty Studies in Historical and Political Science, Series LVI, ‘1 lo.’ ' 34.017. '- I 371 No. 1, Baltimore: The John HOpkins University Press, 1938. Hibbard, Benjamin. A History of Public Land Policies. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1957. Hidy, Ralph. The House of Baring in American Trade and Finance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1949. Hildreth, Richard. Banks, Banking and Paper Currencies. Boston: Whipple and Damrell, 1840. Hughes, J. R. T., and Rosenberg, Nathan. "The United States Business Cycle Before 1860: Some Problems of Inter- pretation." Economic History Review, Vol. 15, April, 1963. Hunt's Merchants' Magazine. New York. Huse, Charles P. The Financial History of Boston. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1916. James, F. Cyril. The Growth of Chicago Banks: The Formative Years, 1816-1896. Vol. New York Harper and Brothers, 1938. Jenks, Leland H. The Migration of British Capital to 1875. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1927. Jevons, W. Stanley. "On the Frequent Autumnal Pressure in the Money Market, and the Actions of the Bank of England." Journal of the Statistical Society of London. Vol. 29. June, 1866. Jones, Fred M. Middlemen in the Domestic Trade of the United States, 1800-1860. Illinois Studies in the Social Science. Vol. 21, No. 3. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1937. Journal of the American Institute. New York: American Institute of the City of New York. Kane, Edward J. Economic Statistics and Econometrics: An Introduction to Quantitative Economics. New York: Harper and Row, 1968. Kenwood, A. G. "Railway Investment in Britain, 1825-1875." Economics. New Series, Vol. XXXII, No. 127, August, 1965. Keyes, Emerson W. A History of Savings Banks in the State of New York. Albany, 1870. v 9. fit] .n'w" won—H.3— '&"E 1. A; 372 King, W. T. C. History of the London Discount Market. London: George Routledge and Sons. Ltd., 1936. Kinley, David. The Independent Treasuryyof the United States and Its Relations to the Banking of the Country. National Monetary Commission, Washington; 1910. Knapp, J. "Capital Exports and Growth." The Economic Journal. Vol. LXVII. September, 1957. Knowles, Charles E. History of the Bank for Savings in the City of New York, 1819-1929. New York: 1929. Layer, Robert G. Earnings of Cotton Mill Operatives, 1825— 1914. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1955. Link, Robert C. English Theories of Economic Fluctuations, 1815-1848. New York: Columbia University Press, 1959. Loyd, Samuel J. Further Reflections on the State of the Currency. London: P. Richardson, 1837. Loyd, Samuel J. A Letter to J. B. Smith, Esq., President of the Manchester Chamber of Commerce. London: P. Richardson, 1840. Macesich, George. "Sources of Monetary Disturbances in the United States, 1834-1845." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 20. September, 1960. Manchester, England, Report of the Chamber of Commerce. December 12, 1839. McCulloch, John R. Essays on Interest, Exchange, Coins, Paper Money and Banks. Philadelphia: A. Hart, 1851. McGouldrick, Paul F. New England Textiles in the Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1968. McGrane, Reginald C. Foreign Bondholders and American State Debts. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1935. McGrane, Reginald C. The Panic of 1837. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1924. McMaster, John B. A History of the People of the United States. Vol. 6. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1906. 373 Martin, Joseph G. SeventyeThree Years History of the Boston Stock Market. Boston: J. G. Martin, 1871. Matthews, R. C. O. A Studyrin Trade Cycle History. Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954. Meerman, Jacob P. "The Climax of the Bank War: Biddle's Contraction, 1833-1834." Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 71. August, 1963. Merlin, Sidney D. The Theory of Fluctuations in Contem- porary_Economic Thought. New York: Columbia Uni- versity Press, 1949. Miller, Harry E. Banking Theories in the United States Before 1860. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1927. Mints, Lloyd W. A History of Banking Theory, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1945. Mitchell, R. R., and Deane, P. Abstract of British His- torical Statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer- sity Press, 1962. Morison, Samuel E. The Oxford History of the American People. New York: Oxford University Press, 1964. Myers, Margaret G. The New York Moneerarket: Origins and Development. Vol. 1. New York: Columbia University Press, 1939. Nevins, Allan. History of the Bank of New York and Trust Company. New York: 1934. Niles National Register. Washington: W. O. Niles. Nolte, Vincent. Fifty Years in Both Hemispheres. New York: Redfield, 1854. North, Douglass C. "Early National Income Estimates of the United States." Economic Development and Cultural Change. Vol. 9, No. 3. April, 1961. North, Douglass C. "The United States Balance of Payments, 1790-1860." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 24. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960. North, Douglass C. Growth and Welfare in the American Past. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1966. 374 North, Douglass C. The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790-1860. New York: W. W. Norton, 1966. Palmer, John H. The Causes and Consequences of the Pressure Upon the Money—Market. London: P. RIchardson, 1837. Parker, William N., and Whartenby, Franklee. "The Growth of Output Before 1840." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 24. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960. Parsons, Burke A. British Trade Cycles and American Bank Credit: Some Aspects of Economic Fluctuations in the United States, 1815-1840. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Economics, University _ i of Texas, 1958. Patriot. "Causes of the Present Crisis." Patriot. Charleston: 1837. Payne, Peter L., and Davis, Lance E. The Saving Bank of Baltimore, 1818-1866. The John Hopkins University Studies in Historical and Political Science, Series 72, No. 2. Baltimore: The John Hopkins University Press, 1954. Potter, J. "Atlantic Economy, 1815-1860: The United States of America and the Industrial Revolution in Britain." In Pressnell, L. S. ed. Studies in the Industrial Revolution. London: The Athlane Press, 1960. Powell, Ellis T. The Evolution of the Money Market, 1835- 1915. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966. Publius, (James DePeyster Ogden). Remarks on the Currency of the United States. New York: Wiley and Putnam, 1840. Putnam, George P. American Facte. London: Wiley and Putnam, 1845. Ratchford, B. U. American State Debts. Durham: Duke University Press, 1941. Redford, Arthur. Manchester Merchants and Foreign Trade, 1794-1858. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1934. Redlich, Fritz. The Moulding of American Banking, Men and Ideas. 2 Vols. New York: Hafner Publishing Co., 1947—1953. 375 Redlich, Fritz. "Bank Money in the United States During the First Half of the Nineteenth Century." Southern Economic Journal. Vol. 10, No. 3. January, 1944. Rezneck, Samuel. "The Social History of an American Depres- sion, 1837-1843." American Historical Review. Vol. LX, 1935. Robbins, Roy M. Our Landed Heritage. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1942. Rothstein, Morton. "Antebellum Wheat and Cotton Exports: A Contrast in Marketing Organization and Economic Development." Agricultural History. Vol. XL, No. 2, 1966. Ryner, Ira. "On the Crises of 1837, 1847 and 1857 in England, France, and the United States." University Studies, University of Nebraska. Vol. V, No. 2, April, 1905. Sakolski, A. M. The Great American Land Bubble. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1932. Salomons, David. Reflections on the Connection Between Our Gold Standard and the Recent Monetary Vicissitudes. London: P. Richardson, 1843. Scheiber, Harry N. "George Bancroft and the Bank of Michigan, 1837—1841." Michigan History. XLIV, March, 1960. Scheiber, Harry N. "The Pet Banks in Jacksonian Politics and Finance, 1833-1841." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 23, No. 2, June, 1963. Scheiber, Harry N. "The Commercial Bank of Lake Erie, 1831— 1843." Business History Review. Spring, 1966. Schmidt, Louis B. "Internal Commerce and the Development of National Economy Before 1860." Journal of Politi- cal Economy, Vol. XLVII. December, 1939. Schmidt, Louis B. "The Internal Grain Trade of the United States." Iowa Journal of History and Politics. Vol. 18, No. 1. January, 1920. Schlesinger, Arthur M. Jr. The Age of Jackson. Boston: Little Brown and Company, 1945. Schneider, David M. The History of Public Welfare in New York State, 1609-1866. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1938. 376 Scriber, Peter. (Davis, C.A.). To the People of the United States. New York: 1849. Seaman, Ezra C. Essayron the Progress of Nations. Detroit: Geiger and Co., 1846. Shannon, F. A. "A Post Mortem on the Labor Safety-Valve Theory." Agricultural History. Vol. 29. January, 1945. Shapiro, Eli; Solomon, Ezra; and White, William L. Money and Banking, 5th ed. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1968. Silberling, Norman J. "British Prices and Business Cycles, 1779-1850." The Review of Economic Statistics. E Vol. 5, Prel. October, 1923. Supplement 2. 5'" Smith, Walter B., and Cole, Arthur H. Fluctuations in American Business, 1790-1860. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1935. Smith, Walter B. Economic Aspects of the Second Bank of the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1953. Smith, Walter B. "Wage Rates on the Erie Canal, 1828-1881." The Journal of Economic History. Vol. 23, No. 3. September, 1963. Statistical History of the United States From Colonial Times to the Present, The. Conn: Fairfield Publish- ers, Inc., 1965. Studenski, Paul, and Kross, Herman E. Financial History of the United States. 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1963. Sumner, William G. A History of American Currency, New York: Henry Holt and Co., 1884. Sumner, William G. A History of Banking in the United States. New York: The Journal of Commerce and Commercial Bulletin, 1896. Taussig, Frank W. The Tariff History of the United States. 8th rev. ed. New York: Capricorn Books, 1964. Taussig, Frank W. "The Tariff, 1830-1860." The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 2. April, 1888. 377 Taylor, George R. The Transportation Revolution. New York: Rinehart and Co., Inc., 1958. Taylor, George R. "American Urban Growth Preceding the Railway Age." The Journal of Economic History. Vol. 27, No. 3. September, 1967. Temin, Peter. The Jacksonian Economy. New York: W. W. Norton and Co., Inc., 1969. Temin, Peter. "The Causes of Cotton-Price Fluctuations in the 1830's." Review of Economics and Statistics. Vol. XLIX. November, 1967. Tilden, Samuel J. Speech of Samuel J. Tilden at New Lebanon, October 3, 1840, on Currency, PEICes, and Wages. New York: New York Public Library. Timberlake, Richard H. Jr. "The Specie Circular and Distri- bution of the Surplus." The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. LXVIII, NO. 2. April, 1960. Timberlake, Richard H. Jr. "Independent Treasury and Mone- tary Policy Before the Civil War." Southern Eco- nomic Journal, Vol. 27, No. 2. October, 1960. Timberlake, Richard H. Jr. "The Specie Standard and Central Banking in the United States Before 1860." Journal of Economic History, Vol. 21, No. 3. September, 1961. Timberlake, Richard H. Jr. "The Specie Circular and Sales of Public Lands: A Comment." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 25, No. 3. September, 1965. Thomas, Brinley. Migration and Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954. Tobin, James. "The Role of Money in National Economic Policy." Controlling Monetary Aggregates. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1969. Tooke, Thomas. A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation. Vols. 2, 3, 4. London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green and Longman, 1838 Trescott, Paul B. "Federal-State Financial Relations, 1790-1860." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 15, No. 3. September, 1955. 378 Trescott, Paul B. "The United States Government and National Income." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century, Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 24. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960. Trotter, Alexander. Observations on the Financial Position and Credit of Such of the States of the North America Union as Have Contracted Public Debts. London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green, and Longman, 1839. Tucker, George. The Theory of Money and Banks Investigated. Boston: C. C. Little and J. Brown, 1839. Tucker, George. Progress of the United States in Population and Wealth in Fiftinears. New York: Hunt's Mer— chant's Magazine Press, 1843. United States, Department of Agriculture, Statistical Bureau, Circular No. 32. Cotton Crops of the United States, 1790-1911. August 15, 1912. Van Deusen, Glyndon G. The Jacksonian Era, 1828-1848. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1959. Van Fenstermaker, J. The Development of American Commercial Banking: 1782-1837. Bureau of Economic and Busi- ness Research Monograph No. 5. Kent: Kent State University Press, 1965. Walker, Amasa. The Science of Wealth. Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1867. Warburton, Clark. "Variations in Economic Growth and Banking Developments in the United States From 1835 to 1885." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 18. September, 1958. Warburton, Clark. "Monetary Disturbances and Business Fluctuations in Two Centuries of American History." In Yeager, Leland B., ed. In Search of a Monetary Constitution. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1962. Ware, Caroline F. The Early New England Cotton Manufactures. New York: Russell and Russell, 1966. Ware, Nathanial. Notes on Political Economy. New York: Leavitt, Trow and Co., 1844. 379 Ware, Norman. The Industrial Worker, 1840-1860. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin Co., 1924. Warren, George, and Pearson, F. A. Prices. New York: John Wiley and Son, 1933. Wender, Herbert. Southern Commercial Conventions, 1837- 1859. John Hopkins University Studies in Historical and Political Science, Series XLVIII, No. 4. Balti— more: The John Hopkins University Press, 1930. Wicker, E. R. "Railroad Investment Before the Civil War." Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 24. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960. Wilburn, Jean A. Biddle's Bank. New York: Columbia Uni- versity Press, 1967. Willett, Thomas D. "International Specie Flows and American Monetary Stability, 1834-1869." Journal of Economic History. Vol. 28. March, 1968. Williamson, Jeffrey G. "International Trade and United States Economic DevelOpment: 1827-1843." Journal of Economic History, Vol. 21, No. 3. September, 1961. Williamson, Jeffrey G. American Growth and the Balance of Payments, 1820-1913. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press, 1964. Wunderlich, Herbert J. "Foreign Grain Trade of the United States, 1835-1860." Iowa Journal of History and Politics. Vol. 33, No. 1. January, 1935. Yeager, Leland B. International Monetary Relations. New York: Harper and Row, 1966. Zevin, Robert B. The Growth of Cotton Textile Production After 1815. (Forthcoming). Governmental Documents New York State, Report of the Bank Commissioners: New York State Assembly, 56th Session, Assembly Document No. 69. 57th Session, Assembly Document No. 102. 58th Session, Assembly Document No. 74. 380 59th Session, Assembly Document No. 80. 60th Session, Assembly Document No. 78. 6lst Session, Assembly Document No. 71. 62nd Session, Assembly Document No. 101. 63rd Session, Assembly Document No. 44. 64th Session, Assembly Document No. 64. 65th Session, Assembly Document No. 29. 66th Session, Assembly Document No. 34. New York State. Assembly, Report of the Select Committee Appointed to Investigate the Banks. 60th Session, 60th Session, Assembly Document No. 328. New York State, Senate, 65th Session Senate Document No. 82. United States, Bureau of the Census. Tenth Census of the United States: 1880. Report on Voluation, Taxation and Public Indebtedness in the United States. Vol. 7. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1884. United States Congress, House, 22nd Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 105. 23rd Congress, lst Session, House Document No. 498. 23rd Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 190. 24th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 21, 65, 77, 62. 25th Congress, lst Session, House Document No. 28, 30. 25th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 79. 25th Congress, 3rd Session, House Document No. 66, 227. 26th Congress, lst Session, House Document No. 172. 26th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 111. 28th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document No. 35. 29th Congress, 1st Session, House Document No. 226. United States Congress, Senate, 23rd Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No. 17. 24th Congress, lst Session, Senate Document No.423. 24th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No. 21, 29. 25th Congress, lst Session, Senate Document No. 7. 25th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No.189. 25th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No.365, 457, 471. 26th Congress, lst Session, Senate Document No. 14. 53rd Congress, 3rd Session, Senate Report No.986. APPENDICES 381 APPENDIX A 382 .mom .Hmm .mm .Homma .roummmmm UHEocoom mo omonsm Hmsoflumz mnu Hem momma ngmHo>Hca coumosflnm “couoocflnmv em .Ho> .ruammz pom oEoocH cH mmflpowm .wuoucou npcoouocHz esp CH mEosoom cmoHHofid one 383 ca mucous =.ommHIom>H .mucmfimmm mo mocmamm mmumum pmuHsD one: .namoz .U mmmHmooo "monoom .mpcmpH>Hp pom umoumucfl pom .mEopH uconnoo pom mo0H>Hom .oocmHmm moose mmflpcmnonozb .mQHCOE ocHzm ooh I vmmv + onov vomm movm I mvvmaa ovomoH mvma oove + mom I ommm vmvm omoH + nmmeoH ovomoa some oonv+ monomI ommmm HmmH vvmmm+ mmmmv mmmmm omva comm + one + woos same Hmma + hmmno momma mvma oomNHI ovom + mmmv vmooH oommHI thmmH hHmHHH Hood oomHm+ wow I mmmm navm mvvmm+ vmmoofl mommmfl ovma oommmI HmHm + momm boom mwmnv+ hmmoma mmmmaa mmma ooom + mmmvHI nvhoH momm omom + momma mnmvoa mmma ooomHI ovmv I hHmoH whom mmmHNI mmomma mvaHH nmma oommmI whom I Hovma wwmv mnnmmI HHHomH mmmvma mmma oommml vmmm I Hmama whom mmmwml omvmma mHNmHH mmmH oomm I vmmmHI HHmoH whom mmmm I NmnoHH ommmoa vmma oooo I mmvv I anon mamm ovmmHI mmomoH mmmnw mmwa oomm I mmm I momm mmmm mommHI wmonm HmmHm mmma oommHI mona + moms mHom mommmI momma mmmmo Hmma oomma+ whom I mmam mnam ommm + Hmnmm Human omwa HOOHmoQ no msamnom oocmamm mpHOQEH muHOme mocoamm muHOQEH muuomxm Hmmw nucoooom uconuou umz 30am oHommm umz mpmne omflpsmnoumz Hmomwm Aooomv mvwfllomwfi OWUCQCCAMAH MO mUfimwamom mmflmpm U®#HCDII.HI¢ msHmANB .384 .NHe .HHe .eo .OON-amm s moHnom .AmOaH ..osH .mnmanHnsa pHoHuanm “scoov Hammond wru ou mmEaB anacoaou Eoum mmumpm pouaso map mo amoumam amoaumaumum mam "mousom .UOaHmm mo use mo mam .mmuooapcodxMImumamoom .ucosmmmom anon mmooaoxmo .mcazouuon Scum muoaoowu mwpoaoxm .m .m .a mssoaoo mo Sum .cm mash -H sunssno .mewH .Om ease osHoso Hews .mOwH-OOwH .Hm nonemomo osHoso new» NOwH-Omen .ocmm smsu mmmar mmmma mmom + mmmmm ommmm mmvm whom v mmmmm mvma Novmm ammo + mmmmm ammmm mmam omcm N voamm vvma mvmmm mmmm I mmmaa mcmm mmma mmm « moon mvma aomcm cmmm I mommm momma mmma mmma « mmama qua qmmma comm I mommm comma comm mmma m hmvva avma ammm mmmv I mamvm cmvma mnmm mmmm m comma coma mnmm ammo + mmmmm mmvam Nvmm mmom m mmamm mmma vmvoa Nome I mmmmm mommm avaoa chm m mmama mmma momm mommaI mvmmm vmmvm momma mono m mmaaa mmma hem mmmma+ mmmom nmmcm mavmm omovm « oaemm mmma mm mmmna+ momma omvmm mmcma mmnva oa ammma mmma mm vmam + mmmma Nmnam mnmm mmmv v mamma «mma ommv ammca+ macmm mvmmm mamv mmmm m mmcmm mmma mach mnmva+ momma mmmam mmmm mmmm ma mmvmm mmma mmmvm momma+ mvmma mmmmm mmmv aamm O vmmqm amma mmamm acnm + mvama vvmvm oamm mmmm ma mmmam omma unmo puaoammo ommuou bmwdamomm mccmq moco>om mmouo amuoe Ho moaduom Iapcwdxm amuoe amuoe oaansm amsumusa mEoumoU sumo» mo mmamm madamomm Hocuo mumaoomm Accomc .mvmalomma mommoamuom pom wuaoammo wmouu cam amocc< .mououapcmmxm .mumawomm amnmpmmll.mld mamfifi 385 TABLE A-3.--Receipts From Public Land Sales by the United States Quarterly, 1830-1845. (1927), p. Lands," Review of Economics and Statistics, ($000) Year First Second Third Fourth Quarter Quarter Quarter Quarter 1830 479 351 520 1059 1831 406 1029 1029 902 1832 597 524 630 1052 1833 608 799 768 1998 1834 1054 982 955 3073 1835 1990 3144 4083 6949 1836 5847 8423 5859 4805 1837 3479 1834 1699 928 1838 548 524 700 2239 1839 1823 1672 1283 1710 1840 950 794 468 536 1841 416 313 367 416 1842 253 591 263 345 1843 551 388 473 638 1844 497 489 525 729 1845 447 531 690 794 Source: Arthur H. Cole, "Variations in Sale of Public IX .ocoo mo mm moahm mommm>< .m .vvma .oa umomsm .mm .aO> .Hmwmwmom aosOauoz moaaz umsmom .mm .aO> .Hmumammm accoapmz mmaaz ”calm mCanOU pow NHOpmam mo amouooo m30a .zoaaumccoz ”mlm m:anOU .OOO .o .Ome .H nonsmaoz .moHnnooz assesses: n.ossr wme-Ome .immOH .suossooc H .02 .mm Omuacb one wO moose camno smamuoms omv cm x.” .roHHHmossz .O Humane: mawH-mme HmaIaa msanOU .Oz .mIa mQESaOO mm meow no CanOU .aO> .moauaaom coo wnoumam mo aosuooc eBOH =.cmmalmmma .mououm .e .mOwH .mm .mmm .mmm .e .OOOH .Ho> .nonHHoo .wOwH-OOOH .OO-NO .mmm .ca .mm .ma umomod flom .m .mvma .a aaumm .vm .aO> snowmammm amsOaumz .mmaaz mmmanmma umIa mchaOU "moouoom .coo.mvammma “ooc.amm.mIomwa nooc.vmmlmmma uooc.mmmImmma "maonmon .muHOQEa nomnzm mmv mm mmm omv omm mmm com mmaa mvma mv. om. ow. mm. cow om mmm omv mmm mom mmm mmva vvma vm. om. mm. ma.a ovv mm amm mav Nam voa mom avw mwma mm. mm.a vm. mm.a mom Naa mmm mom mam mom ccm wmma Nvma mm. ca.a mm. mma.a mam mm «mm vmm mmm mmm mmm mama avma vv. om. mm. oo.a mmm mm Nvm mmm amoa mom vom mmma cvma mm. mc.a mm. mN.a omo cma omm mmm mm mma mma mmm mmma mm mm. cm.a cm. mv.a vow mma omv mmm m moa Noa mvv wmma 13 mm. mm.a ca.a oo.a omm oma mow mom oa mma ama mam omma cm. om.a om. oo.a moo ooa ave amm m ava mma mom mmma mm. m~.a mm. ov.a we oma mmo moo mmma mm. mo.a mm. oo.a om oma mom mmm vmma om. ca.a mm ova omv mmm mmma oo.. mm.a mm ova amv mmm Nmma mm. ca.a mow mom aov mmm amma ov. mm. mva «we ooma omma Hwy Aoccmc Aooov cHOU user: CHOU among mamn mam maouumm mam omam maou mma mama om mash Imam Irmom amos Icmom Irmom Iumm Inmom Iumm Hmow oHOEapamm .U.w.z HoOam poms: :HOU CHOU Hmmrz aomz CHOU Hooam mmoaum moam> umxumz manO> .mOwH-Ome .Homz poo .ssoo .Hson mo nunoexm newnnm omoHsa-.O-< mHmae 387 .om .Hw-He .mo .02 ucoEoOOo omoom .cOammom uma .mmmumcou cumm .Omoo: .mwoumCOU .mwumuw pwuacs .mxcmn muaU xuow 3oz co czoup mmz coo.cmw van aa4n "@UHDOW .coHuobHuumao mru mo ucweaamumCH Ouaru HOm c3mup muwmuo coumouOum aad .u:oE>decoc uOm Omumououd Nocoumz mo xccm amuouaoOHHm< ecu co uwcup oo.ooo.m~amm .ucwE>decoc uOm poumououd mxcmn >uaU xuow 3oz co ammuo oo.coc.ooamm .ucwE>md-coc new moumouOuo xcmm pumuao :0 ummuo oo.eov.ommm .ucwfiocd-coc uOu poumouOuo xcom Oumuao co umcup ma.mam.mamav .ucoexmoIcoc HOM poumououd mxcmn ouHU xuo> 302 so mumcup Ca oco.ccmmo .ucoeomo-coc Hem ovummuOHo coo.omm mo xccm pumuao co ummuon .maooq ucaom cH >Ocom4 mua um canm>od can Caro .aumccHUCaU mo xcmm awaouoEEOU co c3muom .mCaOcoOu mo omscumn amuou anode uoc >mz i .O>h0w0m mDHQHDm OCH WC COAUSDfl-Humfifl HOw 003mmH wwa-MQ MCWWCQMF QUGUMHQUCHI. owl/a a.~cam~ o.ammv mma m.mvm ea m.aam m.~vm m.c~m m.~mm r~.ovam amv «amuoe m.mm~ .zoaz w.mmN m.mm~ o.mm vm m.mma o.mm .xud m.~mm o.oma o.oma .02 m.oo¢ m.omm cmma m.mma .aaa m.omm .UCH m.ooom Oaco m.mmva .ox m.mmva 0.0mm m.oa mo.m~a m.om o.om .ccoe m.oov .mq m.~mm .mma: a.mmm .Mad v.amca m.oma m.oma .OU v.amoa m.oma 0m.om wo.ooa .U.m m.mmva m.mqo Om.vmm o.mmv .U.z v.mma~ m.oco m.mo~ bo.om Oo.mom .o> m.mmm .OZ m.mmm o.mma o.mma .aoo m.omm~ c.0ma o.oma .ccmm o.vmo o.mmm o.mmm .o.z m.vaov .>.Z o.vmo m.vma m.vma .CCOU m.~mm 0.0m 0.0m .H.m ~.mMma .mmmz a.mmm a.mam a.mam .u> a.mmm o.vma vma .:.z m.mmm c.omm omm .02 no» nuances co>Hooem cacuoe .02 .ox .cq .mmaz .ch OHro .ccom .> .z .mmmz “Eoum wuoum Accomv APPENDIX B 388 389 TABLE B-l.--Estimates Of Major Assets, all United States Banks, 1829, 1833-1845. ($000,000) End Of Loans and Discounts Specie Year I II III Ia IIa IIIa IVa Va 1829 200.5 22.1 20 1833 324.1 324 26.6 27 1834 350.8 365.2 365 42.9 43.9 43.9 47.0 44 1835 458.8 457.6 458 39.9 40.0 40.0 44.8 40 1836 519.5 525.1 525 37.5 37.9 37.9 43.3 38 1837 476.3 485.6 486 34.9 35.2 35.2 36.1 35 1838 497.6 492.3 492 44.5 45.1 45.1 48.7 45 1839 460.6 462.9 463 33.1 33.1 33.1 36.7 33 1840 385.8 385.8 387 32.7 34.8 38.0 35 1841 349.8 324.0 324 29.6 28.4 31.6 28 1842 255.5 254.6 255 33.9 33.5 40.1 34 1843 265.5 264.9 265 49.7 49.9 56.6 50 1844 285.5 289 43.8 44.2 51.0 44 1845 311.5 312 41.8 42.0 42 Sources: I and Ia, Thomas S. Berry, Western Prices Before 1861 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1943), p. 588. II and IIa, Hunt's Merchants Magazine, August, 1841, p. 186; Niles' National Register, January 14, 1843, p. 308; and David R. Dewey, Financial History of the United States, 12th ed., New York: Longmans, Green and Co., 1939), p. 225. III. The Statistical History Of the United States From the Colonial Times to the Present (Conn: Fairfield Publishers, Inc., 1965), Series X22, p. 624. IIIa, Jeffrey G. Williamson, American Growth and the Balance of Payments, 1820—1913 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1964), p. 277. IVa, George Macesich, "Sources of Monetary Disturb- ances in the United States, 1834-1845," Journal Of Economic History, Vol. 20 (September, 1960), pp. 430-431. Va, Peter Temin, The Jacksonian Economy (New York: W. W. Norton and Co., Inc., 1969), pp. 186-187. 390 TABLE B-2.--Estimates Of Major Liabilities, all United States Banks, 1829, 1833-1845. I ‘3‘ ($000,000) End Of Note Circulation Deposits Year I II Ia IIa IIIa 1829 61.3 55.6 1833 94.8 75.7 102 1834 101.9 103.7 85.1 83.1 122 1835 148.1 140.3 120.7 115.1 166 1836 146.5 149.2 131.9 127.4 190 1837 115.5 116.1 82.9 84.7 146 1838 135.6 135.2 90.4 90.2 143 1839 111.6 107.0 73.9 75.7 120 1840 106.4 107.3 66.5 108 1841 86.7 83.7 62.6 88 1842 60.2 58.6 55.5 78 1843 76.3 75.2 83.2 117 1844 91.1 90.0 86.2 114 1845 104.9 106.0 96.5 125 Sources: I and Ia, Thomas S. Berry, Western Prices Before 1861 (Cambridge: p. 588. II, Statistical History of the United States from Colonial Times to Present (Conn: Fairfield Pub- lishers, Inc., 1965), Series X39, p. 625; Hunt's Merchants Magazine, August 1841, p. 186; Niles' National Register, January 14, 1842, p. 308. Harvard University Press, 1943), IIa, Hunt's Merchants Magazine, August 1841, p. 186; Niles National Register, January 14, 1842, p. 308. IIIa, Statistical History of the United States From Colonial Times to the Present, Series X34, p. 625. Listed as total deposits. 391 TABLE B-3.--Selected Assets and Liabilities Of Federal Deposit Banks, 1834-1837. ($000,000) Year & Loans and Specie Circu- Private Deposits Of Month Discounts lation Deposits U.S.Treasury 1834 Jan. n.a. 2.92 7.80 n.a. 9.36 Oct. n.a. 4.57 8.07 n.a. 12.00 1835 Jan. 47.36 6.86 15.52 n.a. 9.34 Dec. 62.58 9.59 21.79 n.a. 22.35 1836 Feb. 65.44 10.20 26.24 15.04 28.24 March 64.03 11.07 27.30 15.91 30.81 May 70.16 10.20 29.18 16.72 35.52 June 71.28 10.45 27.97 16.04 37.28 Nov. 115.08 15.52 41.48 26.57 45.06 1837 March n.a 15.31 44.83 29.96 38.96 May n.a 13.33 37.62 30.78 26.86 July n.a 11.43 31.78 30.11 21.04 Aug. 112.9 10.58 32.63 29.49 12.94 Per cent Change Jan. 1835 143% 125% 168% 77%a 382% NOV. 1836 aFebruary 1836-November 1836. Sources: Harry N. Scheiber, "The Pet Banks in Jacksonian Politics and Finance, 1833-1841," Journal of Eco- nomic History, Vol. 23, NO. 2 (June, 1963), p. 203; Niles National Register, April 9, June 4, and July 9, 1836; Financial Register, Vol. 1, 1836, p. 205. 392 o as . moo- amma\e-mmmaxm wqh+ ms + NNH+ Hm + ma . mm + amma\qummma\a Hm + moo- mm + mmmemnmmmaxa mcmoauo 3oz mo xcmm cOHCD mm + 4m . o smma\aummma\a wom+ mm + ma + mm + ma . ma + smma\a-mmma\a mm + ma + ma + mmmaxs-mmma\a Baum mpmumm Nuflo xnos 362 4H + om I 5H . smma\auomma\a wfiw+ 0 mm . mm + Hm . om + amma\anmmma\a om + mm + me + ammaanmmma\a huflo xnow 3oz moaumfid mo xcmm sea. 40 I NH . 0 AH + OH + amma\vuwmmaxv wm4+ mma+ oma+ AHH+ as + AHH+ emma\vusmmH\OH wmo+ oefi+ om~+ mHH+ 44 + mm + wmmwxvuvmmfi\oa xcmm mamuomw wflv- we I me . mm . so + mm . amma\m-mmma\v wm + mm + maH+ so + mHH+ am + smma\muvmmaxoa wmm+ mmm+ ooa+ VHH+ ooa+ moH+ Mmma\vusmmfi\oa .mo .mpgmflpa mo xcmm mhmuhwam moflumn mpflmom coam loo w mnemom COHDMH mucsoowflo coflpmooq unwoxm soapma loo [souflu mflommm paw mcmoq pom xcmm xcmm Isouflu .nmmfluvmmfi .wmpmooq mum >o£9 soflnz ca mmfiuflu no mmumum mnp mo mxamm pom mxcmm uflmommo Umuomamm mo mmfluflaflnmflq pom mummmd Mono: CH mmmcmzo mmmucmoumm mo comflummfiooll.wam mqmdB 393 .mmDMDm Cones: may mo xcmm pcoomm wnp mcflpsaoxm Q .mflommm I muflmomom paw coflpmHDOHHUm .mn unmasooo >HQEmmm< .coflmmmm Spom .manEmmm¢ mgmum xuow 3oz .mnocOHmmHEEoo xcmm mo uuommm .mumum xuow 3oZIpcsm wummmm wuflo xno» Bmz .me .m .mva .Hmnouoo .ocflwmmmz .mucmgoumz m.ucsm .mcmmHHO 3oz .Hbv pomsoooo mumcmm .c0fimmmm pom ~mmmumcou Qumm umwmcmm .mmoumcoo .mmumwm wwwflcb .mmm pamesooo m>Hp50mxm mmsom ~coflmmmm DmH .mmoumcou numm .HHH pcofisoon omsom .sowmmom paw .wmonmcoo Spam .om ucogsooo mmsom .coflmmmm pmH .mmmumcoo gymm .mm .HN mucwfisooo omoom ~coflmmmm pom .mmmnmcou cwvm “mmsom .mmmumcoo .moumam wouHsD ”mmomsom wao+ mo + we I mo + so I mo + amma\mImmmH\m wmm+ 5H + No + mm + om I 46 + smma\mIvmmH\HH mov+ mH + 40 + mm + we I mm + mmmamevmmH\HH meflmm . Qcmm mm I so I mo I smma\mImmmH\m wam+ mo I ma I «H + me I mma+ amma\mIsmmH\HH qu+ as + mmfi+ mmmwmevmmH\HH xcmm Bumuflo wms+ HH I 4H I HooI om I HooI amma\mIommH\m wsm+ mm + me + mm + we I mm + smma\mImmmH\m meI «m + mm + mm + 46 + mm + II ommfimemmmaxm mxcmm mammauo 3oz moflumm muflmom coflm too a mpflmom coflpma mucsoowflo coflumooq Icmoxm sofluma loo IDOHHU mfloomm pom mcmoq pom xcmm xcmm Isouflo .UmDCHDCOUII.VIm mqm<8 .mmm .omm .omm .mmm .mmm .Hmm .66 .Ammma .mmmum aowcmumao .wuoonv H .Ho> .ommHIomsH .maocoom nmflpflum may mo mcoflpmsposflm paw szouw one .NDHMBAOm .h .d paw «coumom .3 .3 «Hmwmo .Q .¢ "mousom .ww.moa .wm.mm .wvm .mnm.vn .wmo mmm .wma.qm .wmm .mmmuo>m wmm.v ucsoomflo mo mpmu xcmma .mmmH wash Hflpcs pcmo mom v mma ovum xcmm .wmcusw ©2oum>o xn pmucooomflo mmcmnoxo mo mHHHQ mmmHOIDmuHm so mums on» ma macaw .woa.wv 394 vo.m oamm.m m.mmm n.v N.mH mvma No.m mNH.N o.mvm m.m v.mH vvwfl wH.m mnH.N m.omm m.m m.HH mvma mm.m nnm.m v.mqm m.v m.m mvma mm.m mom.v v.wmm w.v w.v vaH mm.m mmm.v 6.00m wuv N.v ovma mm.m vma.m m.mom m.m v.v mmma om.m moo.m «.mmm m.m n.a mmma mm.m va.v >.mmm m.ma w.n 0.0 hmma mm.m Hmm.v m.omm m.>a m.v m.m mmma mm.m HB.N m.mmm H.mH m.m v.0 mmma Hm.m mm.m m.HHm m.mH m.m H.m «mma ov.m m>.m m.vom H.ma m.H w.oa mmma mm.m mH.m H.vma H.ma m.m m.m «mma mo.m mm.m m.>om m.mH m.m 0.5 Hmma mm.m Hm.m m.mmfi m.o~ m.a m.m omma popmouu coflpmHsouHU ocwamcm mHOwcoo mucooomflo mocmnoxm CH mowoz mo xcmm Unmamcm mo ucoo mom m mo mpmm wo mHHHm pcmamcm mo poucooo xcmm EH :0 paoflw umxwmz Hmuoe wo xcmm Imam mouoz COflHHsm umow pom maaflm Aooo.oooav .mvaIommH sowmcflx wmuflca may 2H mcofluflwcoo sumpmcozII.mIm mamas 395 TABLE B-6.--Estimates of the United States Money Supply, 1833-1845. ($000,000) End of Year A B C D 1833 113.0 226 168 1834 123.8 187.0 268 172 1835 160.9 268.8 366 246 1836 160.0 277.4 407 276 1837 153.3 198.4 345 232 1838 175.6 226.0 363 240 1839 159.3 185.5 306 215 1840 139.4 172.9 294 286 1841 144.0 149.3 252 174 1842 127.5 115.7 225 258 1843 137.2 159.5 284 194 1844 165.1 177.3 292 214 1845 195.3 201.0 318 241 Sources: A. Report of the Comptroller of the Currency 1896 found in Jeffrey Williamson, American Growth and the Balance of Payments (Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press, 1964), p. 277. B. Thomas S. Berry, Western Prices Before 1861 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1943), p. 588, includes only bank money. C. The Statistical History of the United States From Colonial Times to the Present (Conn: Fairfield Publishers, Inc., 1965), Series X, 281, p. 647, includes only bank money. D. Peter Temin, The Jacksonian Economy (New York: W. W. Norton and Co., Inc., 1969), pp. 61, 159. 396 TABLE B-7.--Interest Rates in London and New York Money Markets and the Bank of England's Discount Rate, Monthly, January 1834-December 1844. Month and London Bank of New Yorka Year England January 1834 3 1/4 4 15,18,24 February 3 4 Business unsettled March 2 3/4 4 Rates High and April 3 4 Variable May 3 1/4 4 " June 3 1/4 4 " July 3 1/4 4 " August 3 1/4 4 " September 4 4 " October 3 3/4 4 " November 3 3/4 4 " December 3 3/4 4 12,10,8 January 1835 3 3/4 4 5 February 3 1/4 4 5 March 3 1/2 4 5 April 3 3/4 4 5 May 3 3/4 4 5 June 4 4 5 July 4 4 5 August 3 1/2 4 5 September 3 3/4 4 5 October 3 3/4 4 5 November 3 3/4 4 5 December 3 3/4 4 8, 10 January 1836 3 3/4 4 10 February 3 3/4 4 10 March 3 1/2 4 12 April 3 1/4 4 12,15 May 3 1/4 4 15,18 June 4 4 15,12 July 4 4, 4 1/2 15,18 August 4 1/2 4 1/2 18,24 September 5 5 24 October 5 5 24,36 November 5 1/2 5 24,30 December 5 1/2 5 24,30 January 1837 5 1/2 5 16,20,13 February 5 1/2 5 15,21,18 March 5 1/2 5 18,20,27 April 5 1/2 5 27,26,30 May 4 1/2 5 27,32 June 4 1/2 5 18,9,6 July 4 1/2 5 7 1/2 August 4 5 7 1/2 TABLE B-7.--Continued. Month and 397 London Bank of New Yorka Year England September 3 1/2 5 7 1/2, 6 1/2 October 3 1/4 5 6 1/2 November 3 1/4 5 6,9 December 3 1/2 5 ‘ 10 January 1838 3 1/2 5 11 February 3 5 12 March 3 5 12,18 April 2 3/4 5 18,12 May 2 1/2 5 lo; 9! 7 June 2 3/4 5 7, 6 July 3 5,4 6 August 2 3/4 4 6, 7 September 3 4 6, 7 October 3 4 6, 7 November 3 1/4 4 6, 8 December 3 1/2 4 7, 9, 7 January 1839 3 3/4 4 6, 9 February 3 3/4 4 6, 9 March 3 3/4 4 6, 9 April 3 3/4 4 6, 9 May 4 4,5 6, 9 June 5 5,5 1/2 9 July 5 1/2 5 1/2 11,12 August 6 6 12,15 September 6 1/2 6 15,18,21 October 6 1/2 6 21,30 November 6 1/2 6 20,33,36 December 6 1/2 6 18,15, 9 January 1840 6 6,5 9 February 4 3/4 5 9,12 March 4 3/4 5 9,12 April 4 3/4 5 12, 7 May 4 1/4 5 7 June 4 3/4 5 6, 8 July 4 1/2 5 8, 5 August 4 1/2 5 5, 7 1/2 September 4 3/4 5 6, 7 October 5 5 6, 7 November 6 5 6, 7 December 5 3/4 5 6, 7 January 1841 5 1/2 5 6, 7 February 5 5 6, 7 March 5 5 6, 7 April 4 1/2 5 6, 7 May 4 1/2 5 6 June 5 5 6 July 4 1/2 5 6 398 TABLE B-7.--Continued. Month and London Bank of New Yorka Year England August 4 1/2 5 6 September 4 3/4 5 6, 7 October 5 5 6, 7 1/2 November 5 1/2 5 6, 9 December 5 5 9,12 January 1842 4 3/4 5 9,12 February 4 1/2 5 9,12 March 3 3/4 5 9,12 April 3 3/4 5,4 8 May 3 1/4 4 8 June 3 1/2 4 8 July 3 1/4 4 8 August 3 4 7 1/4 September 2 1/2 4 7 October 2 3/4 4 6 1/2, 6 November 2 1/2 4 6, 6 1/2 December 2 1/2 4 6, 9 January 1843 2 1/2 4 6 February 2 1/4 4 6, 5 March 2 4 5, 6 April 2 4 5 May 2 4 5, 4 1/2 June 2 1/4 4 5, 4 1/2, 3 1/2 July 2 1/4 4 4 August 2 4 3 1/4, 4 September 2 1/4 4 3 1/2, 4 October 2 1/4 4 3 1/2, 4 November 2 1/4 4 3 1/2, 4 December 2 1/2 4 3 1/2, 4 January 1844 2 1/4 4 4 February 2 4 4 March 2 4 4, 5 April 2 4 5 May 1 3/4 4 5 June 2 4 5 July 2 4 5 August 1 3/4 4 5 September 2 4, 2 1/2, 3 5, 5 1/2 October 2 1/4 3, 2 1/2 5 November 2 3/4 3, 2 1/2 5, 5 1/2 December 2 3/4 2 1/2 5 aRates quoted are for the beginning, middle, and end of each month. Source: Erastus B. Bigelow, The Tariff Question (Boston: Little Brown and Co., 1862), p. 206. 399 TABLE B-8.--Foreign Exchange Rates, Dollar and Pounds Year and Month January, 1834-December, Sixty Day Bills Per cent Premium on Nominal Para 1843. Sovereigns January 1834 February March April May June July August September October November December January 1835 February March April May June July August September October November December January 1836 February March April May June July August September October November December January 1837 February March April May June July 1837 August September ooxoxnoqooqqqoxqquoooxokoxoookokoxoooooqowqowqqmpNI—aufldI—aI—IN DJ H 1/4 1/2 1/2 3/4 1/2 1/4 1/2 1/4 1/2 3/4 1/2 1/4 3/4 1/2 1/4 1/4 1/2 3/4 3/4 3/4 1/2 1/4 1/2 3/4 1/4 1/2 3/4 1/2 1/2 I kOCD\I\I\IO\\I\I\IUIUJNII>I—‘NNN I [.4 I \Jxlxlooookoooomoxokokoxo I I I—‘ I-‘ \ N 1/2 1/4 1/2 1/2 3/4 3/4 1/4 1/2 1/4 1/2 1/2 1/4 3/4 1/2 1/2 1/4 3/4 1/4 1/2 1/2 'U'U'U'U'“U'U'U'U'U'U'U'U'U'U*O'U"OU'U’UU’U'U'U’UUU'OU'UU'UFO’O'U'U'U'U'U'O"O'O(LONG I—' Hoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo\lwwawNto NI—‘NH OKONCD \I \ 00 I \OKOKOKOKOQ‘OWW00000000000KDKDKDKDKOKOKOKDKDKOWKDKDQDWnD-U'IwMN 1/29 l/2p l/2p 1/8p 1/4p 1/8p 1/8p 1/8p 1/89 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 3/8p 5/8pb P 1/8p 1/2p 1/8p TABLE B-8.--Continued. 400 Sixty Day Bills Year and Per cent Premium Sovereigns Month on Nominal Para October 14 -15 p 13 1/2-14 3/4p November 15 1/2 -16 p 14 3/4-15 1/4p December 14 -14 1/2 p 14 3/4-15 1/4p January 1838 9 1/8 -10 1/4 p 11 3/8-12 1/2p February 9 — 9 1/2 p 12 1/2-13 3/4p March 7 1/4 - 7 1/2 p 11 3/8-11 7/8p April 4 1/5 - 5 p 10 1/4-11 3/8p May 6 1/4 - 6 3/4 p 9 1/8-10 1/4p June 8 - 8 1/2 p 9 1/8-10 1/4p July 7 1/2 - 8 1/2 p 9 1/8-10 1/4p August 7 1/2 - 8 1/2 9 1/8 September 9 - 9 1/4 9 1/8 October 10 1/4 -10 1/4 9 1/8 November 9 1/4 - 9 1/2 9 1/8 December 10 -10 1/4 9 1/8 January 1839 9 1/8 - 9 5/8 9 1/8 February 8 7/8 — 9 1/8 9 1/8 March 8 5/8 - 8 7/8 9 1/8 April 8 1/2 - 9 3/8 9 1/8 May 8 1/2 - 8 7/8 9 1/8 June 9 3/8 - 9 5/8 9 1/8 July 8 7/8 - 9 3/8 9 1/8 August 9 1/8 - 9 7/8 9 1/8 September 8 1/2 - 8 7/8 9 1/8 October 9 5/8 -10 1/4 9 1/8 November 6 7/8 - 7 3/8 9 1/8-10 1/4 December 8 5/8 - 9 1/8 9 1/8-10 1/4 January 1840 7 3/8 - 8 1/2 9 1/8-10 1/4 February 8 - 8 1/2 9 1/8-10 1/4 March 8 - 8 1/4 9 1/8-10 1/4 April 7 3/8 - 8 1/4 9 1/8-10 1/4 May 7 5/8 - 8 1/4 9 1/8-10 1/4 June 7 3/8 - 8 9 1/8-10 1/4 July 6 5/8 - 7 1/8 8 7/8 August 6 3/8 - 6 7/8 8 7/8 September 6 3/8 - 6 7/8 8 7/8 October 8 - 8 1/4 8 7/8 November 8 5/8 - 8 7/8 8 7/8 December 8 1/2 - 8 7/8 8 7/8 January 1841 8 1/2 February 8 March 8 April 7 May 7 1/2 June 8 1/4 July 8 1/2 August 8 1/2 401 TABLE B-8.--Continued. Sixty Day Bills Year and Per cent Premium Sovereigns Month on Nominal Para September 9 October 9 3/4 November 10 December 9 1/4 January 1842 8 3/4 February 8 1/4 March 8 1/4 April 6 1/2 May 7 1/2 June 8 July 7 1/2 August 6 1/4 September 7 3/8 October 8 1/8 November 6 1/4 December 6 1/2 January 1843 5 1/2 February 5 3/8 March 6 April 5 3/4 May 7 1/4 June 8 1/2 July 8 3/4 August 9 1/4 September 9 1/4 October 9 1/4 November 8 1/2 December 8 1/2 aNominal par was $4.4444 = 1 b. p = premium; d = discount; high and low for each month. bMay, 1837-December, 1837 s = L May 1837 $4.95-$5.05 September 1837 June 1837 $5.25-$5.35 October 1837 July 1837 $5.45-$5.475 November 1837 August 1837 $5.30-$5.35 December 1837 Sources: United States, Congress, Senate, 25th Session, Senate Document No. 457, pp. Appendix Table B-lO. Walter B. Smith $5.35-$5.38 $5.05-$5.10 $5.10-S5.l3 $5.10-$5.13 Congress, 2nd 92-97; and Arthur H. Cole, Fluctuations in American Business, 1790-1860 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1935),pp. 187, 190-191. Hazard's United States Commercial and Statistical Register, Vol. 4, March 1841, pp. 154-155; June 1841, pp. 408-409. United States Congress, House, 25th Congress, 3rd Session, House Document 227, pp. 646-647. 402 TABLE B—9.-—Value of the Pound Sterling in Dollars. Per cent of Dollars and Cents Par (Nominal)a Per Pound Sterling Par $4.4444 Premium 1/4% .4555 1/2% .4666 3/4% .4777 1 4.4888 2 .5333 3 .5777 4 .6222 5 .6666 6 .7111 7 .7555 8 .8000 9 .8444 10 .8888 11 .9333 12 .9777 13 5.0222 14 5.0666 15 5.1110 20 5.3332 aPrior to the Act of June 28, 1834, the ratio of gold to silver at the mint was 15.1. The American eagle ($10) of the old coinage--previous to July 31, 1834—- contained 247.5 grains of pure gold. As the British sovereign (51) contained when minted 113 1/623 grains of pure gold, the gold par was $4.65 to the pound, while the legal par was $4.44 to the pound. After the Act of June 28, 1834, mint ratio was changed to 16 1/464 to 1. New eagle contained 232 grains of pure gold and the gold par was equal to the exchange rate at $4.87075 to the pound. After the Act of January 18, 1837, the mint ratio was changed to 15.988+ to 1. Exchange rate was then, assuming that British sovereigns were of full weight and standard fineness, $4.86656 to the pound. It was estimated by the Assey Office at the Philadelphia Mint in 1837 that the average weight of British sovereigns was 112.8577 grains. Source: United States, Congress, House, 25th Congress, 3rd Session, House Document No. 227, pp. 648-649. 403 TABLE B-10.-—The Condition of the New York City Banks July 1834-May 1844. Month and Loans and Specie Circu- Deposits U.S. Year* Discounts lation Deposits July 1834 24364 2494 3687 January 1 1835 30480 4359 4994 11594 January 1 1836 43240 4731 7569 14849 9292 June 1 1836 44572 6389 8578 18141 January 1837 46246 4731 9693 14855 10135 Junea 1837 38434 1711 5284 11300 3908 July 1837 37725 1710 5575 10929 3152 August 1837 36988 1758 6061 11481 708 September 1837 35308 1782 5492 11890 587 October 1837 33724 1966 5541 13384 431 November 1837 32078 2100 4827 12969 237 December 1837 31070 2374 4004 12843 131 January 1838 34057 2875 3608 12497d February 1838 31038 2623 3008 11725 134 March 1838 30489 2740 2657 11180 110 April 1838 29729 3329 2322 11458 35 May 1838 28220 6571 3180 12600 130 January 1839 35947 5008 5494 13201 January 1840 26900 4495 4029 12456 Januaryb 1841 22763 3776 4153 10639 JanuaryC 1842 21583 3341 4151 9396 January 1843 29579 7280 4631 15453 August 1843 36514 12966 5309 23476 May 1844 42130 8486 5894 25001 * Unless otherwise indicated the first week of the month. aReport of the Bank Commissions given the following for May 25, 1837: $43,649,000, $3,092,000, $6,836,000, $12,680,000. b18 Safety Fund Banks. c20 Safety Fund Banks. dFinancial Register gives $12,491,000. New York State Report of Bank Commissioners, New York State Assembly, 56th Session, Assembly Document 69; 57th Session, Assembly Document 102; 58th Session, Assembly Document 74; 59th Session, Assembly Document 80; 60th Session, Assembly Document 78; 60th Session, Assembly Document 328; 6lst Session, Assembly Document 71; 62nd Session, Assembly Document 101; 63rd Session, Assembly Document 44; 64th Session, Assembly Document 64; 65th Session, Assembly Document 29; 66th Session, Assembly Document 34; Financial Register, Vol. I. Sources: 404 .om .oz ucmEsooo mmsom ~coflmmmm ama .mmmumcou cumm mmmuocoo mopmpm Umuflsa “Hm .oz uaoesooo mumcmm .coflmmmm cam npwm sopwcom .mmmwmcoo mmumum pmpficb “mmv .oz namedooo mpwcmm coflmmmm .oz Dcmfisooo pma smmmumcoo spvm opmcmm ~mmmnmcoo wmumvm UmpHcD “mmm .mmsom .mmmumcoo mwmcom .QOHmmmm pmH .mmmmmcoo nuvm ~mpmcmm .mmmuvcoo mmumum wmuHcD "mousom .mxcmm pflmommo mpflo H0005 mo ammo ummp .hmmfi .H magnIhmmH .om 0:060 .Amma .mfi ssznmmH .mm HHHQ60500060 .xcmm mOHEmfiOOE OSIIv Mona ~.OU CM##MSQME mflu5 m0 Mcmm stHHOE/w MO xcmm Org OHOB mxcmn 03H. N66m . .‘sHmH.... , .NHOH mmmmfi onmma >H56I0csw mqam mama nmv ommwa nsmwfl sszHflum¢ 0mmm Hmsa kmma Hmmma 05mmfi gousz.Q0m Amos mmmn Ammo mkka Ammo mmaa Amev nmmva mmaa 00060006 Ahoy hmms fume hvma Adel Hflmm Amvv ommva 0mma 00ns0>oz Ammo MNSOH Ammo mmmfl Ammo mmmm xmvv mmooa ommH 0000000 Ammo meHH Ammo Hmwa Amps mnam 1061 mused mmma 000600000 Away mmmma Ammo mesa .msv mem¢ Ammv momma mmaa 005004 1001 Hemma Ammo osmm 1601 maav Axel 6000a 0mmH sass qmwmfi smma 060m oovoa 0mma 0:56 ommm omMH mama NNmVH mmmfi >000000m Umaflmomma paofluma pmucsoomflm Ham» \AHDmMOHB IDOHHU Gmflommm GQM mCMOA 0C0 £pCOZ m0000m 00uflco Aooowv .smmfi .sHsHImumsHQ0m .suflo xuow 302 ca mxcmm pflmomoo mafipmmq 05p wo mmHuHHHQMHA pom mummmd HOmmzln.HHIm mqmme 405 TABLE B-12.-—Quarter1y Indications of Monetary Conditions in the United Kingdom 1833-1842. (£000,000) Value of Year and Average Yield on Net Note Bank of Total Note Bills of Quarter Market Consols Circula- England Circulation Exchange Rate of Per Cent tion in Note Cir- in England Created in Discount England culation and Wales England Per Cent and Wales and Wales 1833 1 2.5 3.43 19.3 50.8 2 2.9 3.38 19.3 48.3 3 2.7 3.39 19.8 51.6 4 3.3 3.41 10.2 18.2 28.4 51.8 1834 1 3.1 3.35 10.2 19.1 29.3 53.3 2 3.1 3.27 10.5 18.9 29.4 50.9 3 3.5 3.31 10.2 19.1 29.3 55.6 4 3.8 3 30 10.7 18.0 28.7 51.8 1835 1 3.5 3 28 10.4 18.6 29.0 56.7 2 3.8 3.27 10.9 18.3 29.2 57.2 3 3.8 3.32 10.4 18.2 28.6 58.3 4 3.8 3.29 11.1 17.3 28.4 57.4 1836 1 3.6 3.29 11.4 18.1 29.5 64.0 2 3.5 3.27 12.2 17.9 30.1 64.8 3 4.5 3.31 11.7 18.1 29.8 78.1 4 5.3 3.34 12.0 17.4 29.4 73.4 1837 1 5.5 3.33 11.0 18.4 29.4 74.5 2 4.8 3.30 10.9 18.2 29.1 63.0 3 3.8 3.28 10.1 18.9 29.0 63.1 4 3.4 3.22 10.9 17.9 28.8 58.1 1838 1 3.2 3.26 10.9 19.0 29.9 63.5 2 2.7 3.18 11.7 19.0 30.7 62.9 3 2.9 3.19 11.4 19.7 31.1 71.8 4 3.2 3.19 12.2 18.2 30.4 68.2 1839 1 3.8 3.23 12.3 18.4 30.7 72.9 2 4.3 3.21 12.3 18.1 30.4 74.0 3 6.0 3.28 11.1 18.0 29.1 82.0 4 6.5 3.31 11.4 16.3 27.7 74.7 1840 1 5.2 3.30 10.8 16.8 27.6 76.8 2 4.4 3.26 11.1 16.9 28.0 73.6 3 4.6 3.33 10.0 17.2 27.2 79.3 4 5.6 3.37 10.4 16.1 26.5 70.7 1841 1 5.2 3.37 10.0 16.5 26.5 75.5 2 4.8 3.33 10.3 16.6 26.9 70.4 3 4.6 3.35 9.1 17.6 26.7 76.4 4 5.2 3.38 9.5 16.7 26.2 64.1 1842 1 4.3 3.36 8.3 16.9 25.2 67.9 2 3.5 3.25 8.3 17.8 26.1 63.8 3 3.1 3.26 7.9 19.9 27.8 62.5 4 2.6 3.19 8.4 18.8 27.2 55.2 aNote circulation of private and joint stock banks. No information given as to intra-bank holdings. Source: R. C. 0. Matthews, A Study in Trade Cycle History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954), pp. 199, 201. 4(16 TABLE B-l3.--Major Liabilities, New York City Banks, January 1837-May 1838. ($000) Deposits Amount Due Out- side the City Note U.S. To Other From Other Net Date No. of Circu- Treas- Private Banks and Banks and Bankers Banks lation ury Corporations Corporations Balances (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Jan. 1837 21 8822 7176a 12510 14245b June 1837 21 5284 3908 11300 5093 5447 + 354 July 1837 21 5575 3152 10929 6218 5761 - 457 Aug. 1837 21 6061 708 11481 7190 6216 - 974 Sept. 1837 21 5492 587 11890 6745 6720 - 25 Oct. 1837 21 5541 431 13384 5277 6686 +1409 Nov. 1837 21 4827 237 12969 5711 6829 +1118 Dec. 1837 21 4004 131 12843 5884 6770 + 886 Jan. 1838 22d 3608 n.g. 12497C 11284e 11835f + 551 Feb. 1838 21 3008 134 11725 6329 5833 - 496 Mar. 1838 21 2657 110 11180 6321 5108 -1213 Apr. 1838 21 2322 35 11458 6273 4887 -1386 May 1838 21 3180 130 12600 6049 4175 -1874 aThis figure is for the Safety Fund Banks. bThis is the total amount due all banks and corporations which performed banking functions inside and outside the city. The comparable figure for June 1837 was $8,270,000. CListed as deposits, no mention made of Treasury deposits. dManhattan Company included. eTotal due all banks and corporations both inside and outside the city. fTotal due from all banks and corporations both inside and outside the city. Sources: Financial Register, Vol. 1, pp. 92, 93, 143, 152, 157, 170, 224, 287, 319, 320, 349, 408. New York State, Assembly, 6lst Session, Assembly Document No. 71. United States, Congress, House, 25th Congress, 2nd Session, House Document, No. 79, pp. 342-345. United States, Con- gress, Senate, 25th Congress, 2nd Session, Senate Document No. 471, pp. 816-817. 407 own. .02 #Cmcanuog KAHQEmvmmAN ~0AHQE®mmmN ##OW skflHQEmmmfl. smuhwwm MHOW 3&2 "QOHDOW 00>Hm 00: u .m.: 0000 00000 0000 0000 00000 0000 0000000 m0mm 0m000 0000 0000 00000 0000 000000600 .0.0 .0.0 0000 0000 00000 0000 0000 0000 00000 0000 m0mm 00000 0000 00060 m000 m0000 m0m0 0000 00000 0000 0000000 .0.0 .0.0 0000 .0.0 0m00m 0000 0000 mmmm 00000 0000 0000 00000 0000 002 000m 0m0m mmm0 0000 m0000 0000 0000000 .0.0 .0.0 .0.0 00mm 00000 0000 0000000 mmmm 0m00 0000 0000 00000 0000 00002 m00m .0.0 0mm0 0m00 0mm0m 0000 0000000 0000 ~m00 0000 00000 0000 00000002 m000 0mmm 0000 00000 0000 00060 .0.0 0m00 0000 00000 0000 0000000 0000 00mm 0000 ~00m0 0000 00060 0000 0mm0 0000 00000 0000 0000000 0m00 0000 000 mmmm0 0000 0000000 muwmommo .0>ow 0000ommo £00000 00650000o mmuwum ©0006: 005p0>0ch Isou0o 0000mm paw 06000 mumo 000000 .0000I0000 .00000 0000 000000 0000 0000 302 00 000000000 000II.00I0 00000 I408 0 00 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0I0\0 0 0I0\0 0000 000000600 0 00 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 00x0 0I0\0 0 0I0\0 0 0I 006 0000 000000 0 00 0 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0I0\0 00\0 I 006 0000 0000 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0I0\0 00\0 I 006 0000 0000 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 0 0I 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I0\0 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 00060 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I0\0 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 006 0000 00002 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I0\0 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 006 0000 00000000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I0\0 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 006 0000 0000000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 00000000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 00000>oz 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00x0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 0000000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00x0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 000000600 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I I 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 000000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00x0 I 006 00\0 I 006 00\0 I 006 0000 0000 0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 0 0 0I 0 00\0 00\0 00\0 I 006 0000 0000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 00060 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 00000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00x0 00\0 006 0000 00000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 0000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00x0 006 0000 00000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 00000>0z 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 0000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 000000600 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I .0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 0000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 0000 0 0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00x0 00\0 006 0000 00060 0 0I0\0 00x0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 00000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00\0 006 0000 00000000 0 0I0\0 00\0 0I 0 0 0I0\0 00\0 00x0 006 0000 0000000 00000 0:00000 302 cmccm>wm couwoa0mco 00090000m 000m00U000£6 coumom 600 000% Ill {ILI-| Ill." .0000 00002I0000 0000000 .0000 0000 302 00 00000000 00000000 00 000006II.00I0 00000 I409 cN\N o IN\H N u NIN\H N u NIN\H q o N ©N\H NI N UN\H I Ham ONNH mesa wqu N w NIN\H N wv\N NIv\H N wN\H NIN\H N @N\N NvaH v cva I Ham oqNH Na: oNxH o I N m NIN\H N cN\N NI N w NIN\N N wq\N NIN\H N cN\H I Ham ONNH HHHQ< oN\H v I v m NIN\H N wva NI N @ NIN\N N mv\N NIN\H o waH I Ham ONNH scum: a N IN\H N w NHI OH v «I N oN\H NI N ©N\H NI o cN\H I Ham oqNH Numsunmm wN\H N I o @ NHI NH c NI N @ NIN\N N ©N\H NvaH N wN\H I Nam ONNH Numscmw ©N\H N I N o NHI NH o NI N UN\H NvaH N @N\H NIN\H N @N\H I Ham NNNH HmnEmomo w OH N .m.: v N N mN\H VHI NH w NHI «H a HI Ham NNNH umnam>oz a N IN\H v a N v u N N m HIN\H wN\N I Ham wv\H I ”ma NNNH umnouoo u N IN\H q o N N v N N cN\H Iv\H UN\N I Ham wN\H I Ham NNNH umngmummm vv\H N IN\N N a NIN\H N wN\H NI N cN\H IN\H wv\H I Ham wva I Ham NNNH umsmz< c N IN\H N v NIN\H N cN\H NvaN H cN\H IN\H wN\H I Ham cq\H I umm NNNH NHsn mN\H H I H n NIN\H N wN\H NIN\N H wN\H IN\H mv\H I Ham mN\H I Ham NNNH mama cN\H H I H aN\H NI N UN\H N N wN\H IN\H nN\H I Ham cv\H I Ham NNNH Nmz wN\H I Mam uNxH NI N wN\H N N wN\H Iqu @N\H I Ham wN\H I Ham NNNH HHHma w H I Ham v NIN\H N o N H UN\H IN\H wN\H I Ham wN\H I Ham NNNH cogmz Ham v NIN\H N a N H waH IN\H ©N\H I Nam wq\H I Ham NNNH Numsunmm @N\N H Iv\H H wN\H NI N n N H wN\H IN\H UN\H I Mam wv\H I Ham NNNH Numscmn cN\N H Iqu H nN\H NI N u HIN\H mN\H IN\H UN\H I Ham UN\H I Ham NNNH umnEmomo cv\N H IN\H H wN\H NI N ©N\H NvaN N ©N\H IN\H wva IN\H wva I Ham NNNH ungm>oz UN\H N vaN N w NIN\H H wN\H NIN\N H mN\N IN\H nN\H IN\H cva I “mm NNNH umnouoo oN\H v I v c N N oN\H NI N meH IN\H mN\N IN\H ©N\H I umm NNNH “magmummm wv\H N IN\N N m NIN\H N ©N\H NIN\H N ©N\N IN\N cN\N IN\N wv\H I Nam NNNH umgmsa vaH N IN\H o v N N c NIN\H N m NvaN H ©N\N HIN\H H wva IN\H NNNH NHsN uNxH N IN\H m c N N u NIN\H N u NIN\H H w HIv\N wN\H I Ham NNNH much u OHI N w OH N w nI m @N\H HIN\H N UN\H NI N n HIN\H NNNH Nmz @ N I N w NI cN\H NI v oN\H NI q ©N\H NIN\H N uN\H I Ham NNNH HHHQ< v N I v uNxH NI N nN\H NI N wN\H NI N wqu NI N m NIN\H H NNNH scum: n N IN\H N @N\H NI N oN\H NI N mN\H NIN\N H wN\N HIN\H H ©N\H NIN\N H NNNH Numsunmm a N I N @N\N NIN\H N oN\H NI N c NIN\N H w NIN\H H wN\H NIN\N H NNNH Numscmw ©N\H N I o NIN\H N a NIN\H N w NI H @N\N HIv\H H w NIN\H H NNNH “magmomo n N IN\H N m NIN\H N w NIN\H N o NI H @N\H HI H wN\N HvaH H NNNH umn5m>oz v N I N c NI v cN\H NIN\H N u NI H wN\H HI H wN\H HI H NNNH umnouoo sumo: mcmmauo 3®Z mecm>mm COumeHmflU QHOEHunm GNSQHQUMHHEQ Couwmom UCM Ham» . UmSCHuQOUII . m Him mqmde .410 mHOENuHmm NHNNHNNNHHNN .NNHH .m .HNNNH .mm>Hm Nam HHNHm "NONNNNNmmzv :HNNHNN ummuo Nam mmumum NmuHca mgu No Emuwxm NcHNcsm NNN ‘NNoHHHm NNNNNNON .NoNINoN .mm .HNmH .mcsn «mmauvma .mm .HNmH .coumr .umumflmom HmowumNumum New NNNouoEEOU mmumum Umuflca m.©ummmm “nmnmm .mm thv .02 ucwEsooo mumcmm ~conmmm mam .mmwuvcou Lumm .mumcmm .mmmnmcou .mmumum wmuwcb "mmousom .cm>Nm #0: u .m.c .mHHNQ unmflm New Ham co ESNEmuQ no uczoomflw ucmo umm .m no U QN\H H I H NN\H HI H NN\N IN\H NN\H I HNN NNxH I Ham NN\H I Ham NNNH scum: a N IN\N H NN\H NI N NN\H HINxH H NN\H IN\H NN\H I Nam NN\H I umm NNNH umnEm>oz NN\H I HNN N NI N NN\N HIN\H H NNN NN\H I HNN NN\H I Ham NNNH umnEmummm NN\H H IN\H H N NIN\H N NNxH HIN\H H NN\H I HNN NNxH I Nam NN\H, I mam NNNH mcsN N N IN\N N N NHI N NN\N HIN\H H NNxH INxH NN\H I HNN NN\N IN\H NNNH Nmz N N IN\N N N NI N NN\N HIN\H H NN\H IN\H NN\H I Ham NN\N IN\H NNNH HNHNN NN\H N I N N NHI HH NNxN HIN\H H .N.c .N.c NN\N IN\H NNNH scum: N N IN\H N N NHI NH NN\N HIN\H H N NI N NN\N NI N NN\N IN\H NNNH Numsunmm NN\N N IN\H N N NHI NNxH HIN\H H .N.: N NIN\H N NN\H IN\H NNNH Numscmn NN\N N IN\H N N NHIN\H NH NN\H HIN\H H NN\H NI N N NIN\H N NN\N IN\H HNNH umnEmomo N N I N N NIN\H N NN\H HIN\H H N N NNxN NIN\H N NN\H IN\H HNNH umnEmummN .N.c .N.c .N.c .N.c NNxH IN\H NN\H I HNN HNNH mczN .N.c .N.c .N.c .N.c NN\H I HNN NN\N IN\H HNNH Na: N N IN\H N N OHIN\H N N NIN\N H N NIN\H N N NIN\H N NN\H IN\H HNNH HHHNN N N IN\N H NN\H NI N NN\H HI H NN\N HIN\H H NN\N NIN\N N NN\H I NNN NNNH umpEmomo NN\H N I N NN\H NI N N NIN\H H N NIN\H H NN\H NIN\N N NNxH I Ham NNNH umn5m>oz NN\N N IN\H N NN\H NINxH N NN\H HIN\H H N NIN\N H NN\H NI N NN\H I Ham NNNH umnouoo N N IN\H N NN\H NI N N NIN\N H NN\H NIN\H N NN\H NI N NN\H I HNN NNNH umnEmummN NN\H N IN\H N N NIN\N N NN\H NIN\H N NN\H NINxH N NN\H NI N NN\H I umm NNNH pmstN NN\H N I N NN\H NIN\H N NN\N NIN\H N N NIN\H N NN\H NIN\N N NNxH I umm ONNH NHNN Npcos mammauo Bmz nmccm>mm coumwaumno coumom cam Ham» .meCHpCOUII.mHIm mqmde APPENDIX C 411 412 TABLE C-1.--Estimates of United States Cotton Prices, 1830- 1845. (Price Per Pound) American Export Price Year Liverpool Midlings New Orleans Per Pound Uplands and Uplands Uplands Gross Weight Cents Pence Centsa Centsb 1830 13.6 6 7/8 8.4 9.9 1831 11.8 6 9.0 9.1 1832 13.7 6 5/8 10.0 9.8 1833 17.5 8 l/2 11.2 11.1 1834 17.6 8 5/8 15.5 12.9 1835 20.6 10 1/4 15.2 16.8 1836 20.3 9 7/8 13.3 16.8 1837 14.2 7 9.0 14.2 1838 14.2 7 12.4 10.3 1839 15.7 7 7/8 7.9 14.8 1840 12.1 6 9.1 8.6 1841 13.5 6 1/4 7.8 10.2 1842 10.5 5 3/8 5.7 8.1 1843 9.1 4 5/8 7.5 6.2 1844 10.1 4 7/8 5.5 8.1 1845 8.3 4 1/8 6.8 5.9 aData is for crop year, 1830 is thus from September 1830 to August 1831. bData is for fiscal year, 1830 is thus from October 1, 1829 to September 30, 1830. Sources: Liverpool upland: Victor S. Clark, History of Manufactures in the United States, 1607-1860 (Washington: Carnegie Institute, 1916), p. 611. American midlings: United States Congress, Senate, Report of the Committee on Agriculture and Fore- station, 53rd Congress, 3rd Session, Senate Report 986, Vol. 2, p. 157. New Orleans Upland: Lewis C. Gray, History of Agriculture in the Southern United States, Vol. 2 (Washington: Carnegie Institute, 1933), p. 1027. Export Price: United States Department of Agriculture, Statistical Bureau, Circular Number 32, Cotton Crops of the United States, 1790-1911, August 15, 1912, pp. 6-7. .m .o .ma .mHmH .mH umsmsm .HHNHIONNH .moumum couNCD on» m0 macaw covuou .wa HNHSUHNU .smmusm HNUNumNumum .musuasofluma wo ucmEuumme .moumum omuNCD "mousom .NNNH .oN “magmummm 0“ NNNH .H Honouoo ma omma mSQB .Hmmw Hmomflw on“ mm mEmm may ma EON£3 Ham» cofluospoum mbp mN Hmmwm 413 N.NH NNN N.HN NNNH NNN NNN NNoN NNNN NNNH N.NN NNN H.NN NNNH NNN NNN NNNH NNNN NNNH N.NN NNN H.NN NNNH NNN NNN NNoN NNNN NNNH N.NH NNN N.NN NNHH NNN NNN NNNH NNNH NNNH N.HN NNN N.NN NNNH NNN NNN NNNH NNNH HNNH N.NH NNH N.NN NNNH NNN NNN NNNH NNNN NNNH N.NN NNN N.HN NNN NHN NNN NNNH HNNH NNNH N.NH NNN N.HN NNHH NNN NNN NNNH HNNH NNNH N.HN NNN N.NN NNN NNN NNN NNHH NNNH NNNH N.NN NHN N.HN NNN NNN NNN NNNH HNNH NNNH N.NH NNH N.NN NNN NNN NNN NNN NNNH NNNH N.NH NNH N.NN NNN NNN NNN HNN NNNH NNNH N.NN NNH N.NN NNN NNN NNN NHN NHHH NNNH N.NN HNH N.HN NNN NNN NNN NNN NNNH NNNH N.NN NNH N.NN NNN NNN NNN NNN NNNH HNNH N.HN NNH N.NN NNN NNN NNN NNN NNNH NNNH NNN .3.o mNcsom mNcsom ooo .z.m .Noum N0 N .3.N .mmHNm mcoHHHNSN mmHNm coHHHH: NOHHHH: mmHNm mmHmm 000 .NH NNN NH :oHNQENNNON NNHN> .mnH NNN NNNHmz .uz umz .mnH NNN mmHNm MOM 6.0mm w COCHmumm HHOQXM acmam mmOHU HmIpOB ucmam mNCHCCDm whmmw I>N5Um I>Nsvm muuomxm cofluoopomm .NNNHINNNH .coHumEchoo NNN coHposNon c “you mmumum NNNNNDII.NIo mHmNe .Nma .m .m .Ho> .wwm unommm mumcmm .coflmmmm cum Nmmmnmaou UHmm .muummuom paw onsuasoflumm c0 mmuuNEEOU mnp mo uuommm .mumcom .mmmnmcoo .mmumum pmuwco «OH .m CESHOU .Hmm .Q .mcmmo cam Hawnouflz “w CESHOU .NNm .Q .mmumum Umufica may we Nuoumflm HNUNumNumum um CESHOU .momINON .am .Ammma .mmoum waNmHo>NCD owpflunfimu ”mmmfluQENUv moflumflumum HNUNHoumNm LmNUNHm mo uomuumba .mcmma mNHHNLm paw Hamnouflz .m .m “N cam H mSEdHOU “moousom .Hmmw Hmomwm .mmumum Umuflca Howllummw hmpcmamo .EOUmCNM pmuNCD Homw NNOH mma Nm NN Nmm NNm o.mH NNH Now NNN mvma Nvoa mma om mN NHm NNN N.ma NON Nvm NNN vvma mam ova mm mN mNm NNN 0.0m mma mHm me mvma NNN Nma mN HN NHN mmm N.NN Nm mmv mmm mvma HmN mma NN No mmm omm N.HH om mmv mmN HNmH HmN mad mm Nm mmN NNN o.mm mma mmv mam ovma HMN ooa ow mN «Hm NHN m.H N mmm mmm mmma A. omm NNH mm NN HNN mom m.Nm Hm NHN mom mmmH 1. Hmm moa mN mN Hmm NNN N.NH HN wmm Nov Nmma A. mmo mm HN mm omm NNN N.NH ow NNm Nov mmma Nmm mm mN mN Nmm Nmm H.NN mN mHm com mmaa mmo NN mm 0N mmm mmm N.N Nm mom Nmm vmma NNN HNI mN mN mmm mmm m.m NH mmm Nom mmaa HNN NN NN mo omm NNN N.m OH NNN Nmm NmmH HNN Ho wN mN NHN NNN m.m om mmm mmm Hmma HNN No om HN NHN mom N.N NH mNm NNN omma muHOQEH Hmuoe .x.D mo .m.D mo coNu uo>o mtoow cum» ucmo Mom ucmo mom .x.D IQEchoo INHNNU coflu CONuOU couuoo couuou mm muuom m4 .x.: Cu muuom muuom Nb oopfl> coNv IQESmcou 3mm wo muuom mo muuom Ixm :ou ou muuom Ixm con Ixm cou IND uo>o Imammcoo couuou wo muuom Ixm .M.D Ixm .M.D IuOU .m.D Ixm cop IuOU .m.D IuOU .m.D I>uumu mpHOQEH 3mm .M.D IEH .&.D mummw INoo .N.: ucmo NNN Ampum» mo mcoNHHNz mum LUNSB mpoow couuou umooxm mpcsom wo mCONHHNZV .NNNHINNNH .oNNHe couuoo :NoHuwsanHchII.NIo NHNNN .mIO paw .NIU moHQmB xflpcmmm< “mmousom 415 m.v + m.m I m.Hm+ m.am+ N.mN+ N.HH+ m.HH+ mNmHINNmH m.ma+ N. I H.0HI N.NHI o.NHI o.m + o.N I NNmHIMNmH H.mm+ N.N + m.mm+ v.mm+ N.mN+ H.NH+ m.om+ MNmHImNmH N.H I m.m + m.mH+ N.oa+ N.m + N. I o.m + NNmHIHNmH N.m I ~.N + N.NNI w.mmI m.mHI N.N I N.NHI avmalovma ~.m + m.HH+ N.mm+ N.mN+ m.Hm+ H.om+ m.mm+ ONmHImmmH m.m + N.m I N.NNI m.omI N.mmI N.m I N.m~I mmmHImmmH o.om+ N.oa+ m.Nm+ N.Nm+ N.mm+ N.ma+ m.Nm+ mmmHINmmH m.mHI N.H + N.oa+ N.N + m.m + m.m + o. NmmHImmmH m.NH+ m. + H.m + m.m + N.oa+ m.m + m.HH+ mmmalmmma o.mHI n.a + m.m + m. + N.m I m.N + m.HH+ mmmHIemmH o.mm+ o.N + o.ma+ m.mH+ H.NH+ m.N + N.N + NmmHImmmH m.N + m-m I m.m + m. + m.m + m.N + m.m + mmmHImmmH m.m + N.Nm+ N. + m.ma+ o.oa+ m.m + N. I mmmHIHmmH m.N I N.N I m.m + o.N + H.N I o.m + m.m + Hmmalomma mooow gnaw .M.D OB mpuomxm coauQESmcou cabpou couuoo manomxm coauou :oNuosoonm COpuou muuomeH «0 muuom mo mpuom couuoo .m.D COppoo .m.D 3mm .x.: coupoo .M.D mENB Ixm .M.D Ixm .M.D .m.D .NNNHINNNH .mmNcNNo pcmu mom EOUmGNM UmuHCD Ucm mopmum pmuNcD .coNpOSUOHm Ucm coNuQESmCOU couuovll.vIU mqmfie 416 TABLE Cu5.~-Monthly Prices of Short‘Stable American Cotton, New Orleans and England, January 1834-January 1845. (Price Per Pound) H———-———. -m--. --——-._. — .. .——.--.——-—- New Orleans Year and Month (Cents) (Pence) (Pence) Series A Series B England Liverpool January 1834 10.3 10 1/2- 9 3/4 February 1834 9.8 10 1/2- 9 March 1834 10.0 10 1/2- 9 1/2 April 1834 10.8 11 -10 May 1834 11.3 11 1/2-11 June 1834 11.3 12 -11. July 1834 11.8 12 -11 1/2 August 1834 11.8 12 -11 1/2 September 1834 11.8 12 -11 1/2 October 1834 14.3 14 1/2-12 1/2 November 1834 13.3 15 -12 1/2 December 1834 15.8 16 -14 January 1835 15.3 15 1/2-14 February 1835 14.8 16 -14 1/2 March 1835 15.8 16 —15 1/2 April 1835 16.0 16 1/2-15 1/2 May 1835 17.0 17 1/4-16 1/2 June 1835 17.0 17 1/2-16 1/2 July 1835 18.5 19 -16 1/2 August 1835 18.5 19 ~18 September 1835 n.g. n.g. October 1835 15.3 15 1/2-15 November 1835 15.3 14 1/2-14 December 1835 14.6 14 1/2-13 January 1836 14.5 15 -13 1/2 10 l/2~ 7 1/2 February 1836 14.5 15 1/2-14 10 1/2- 8 3/4 March 1836 15.5 16 -15 11 1/4- 9 April 1836 16.8 17 -15 12 -10 1/2 May 1836 15.5 16 1/2-15 11 3/4-10 13 - 9 1/2 June 1836 15.5 16 -14 1/2 11 - 9 13 - 8 3/4 July 1836 14.8 15 -14 1/2 10 3/4- 8 1/2 12 1/2- 8 1/4 August 1836 14.8 15 -14 1/2 10 1/2- 8 1/2 11 1/2- 7 3/4 September 1836 n.g. n.g. 11 3/4- 8 3/4 11 3/4- 7 1/2 October 1836 15.0 16 -14 11 3/4- 8 3/4 9 1/2- 6 1/4 November 1836 15.3 16 -14 11 1/4- 7 1/2 9 - 5 December 1836 14.3 14 1/2-13 1/2 11 1/4- 7 1/2 n.g. January 1837 14.1 14 1/2-13 11 1/4- 7 1/2 11 1/2- 7 3/4 February 1837 12.8 13 1/2-12 1/2 10 - 7 11 3/4- 7 1/2 March 1837 13.8 14 -11 ' 8 - 6 9 1/2- 6 1/4 April 1837 11.5 10 1/2- 8 1/2 8 - 5 1/2 9 - 5 May 1837 11.5 n.g. 7 3/4- 5 1/4 8 1/2- 4 3/4 June 1837 n.g. n.g. 7 1/2- 4 3/4 7 3/4- 4 1/4- July 1837 n.g. n.g. 8 - 5 8 - 4 August 1837 11.3 11 1/4-11 1/4 8 - S 8_1/4- 4 1/2 September 1837 9.4 n.g. 8 - 5 1/2 October 1837 9.8 10 - 9 1/2 8 - 5 1/2 November 1837 9.3 9 1/2- 8 1/2 8 - 6 1/2 December 1837 9.1 9 1/2- 8 1/2 8 1/2- 6 3/4 417 TABLE C-5.--Continued. New Orleans Year and Month (Cents) (Pence) (Pence) Series A Series B England Liverpool January 1838 9.1 9 1/2- 9 8 3/4- 7 1/2 February 1838 9.1 9 1/2- 8 8 - 6 1/2 March 1838 8.1 8 1/2- 8 8 1/4- 6 1/2 April 1838 8.8 8 3/4- 8 1/4 8 - 5 3/4 May 1838 9.3 9 1/4- 8 1/2 8 1/4- 5 1/4 June 1838 9.3 9 - 8 1/4 8 1/4- 5 1/4 July 1838 8.4 9 - 8 1/4 8 1/4- 5 1/2 August 1838 9.3 9 - 8 1/2 8 - 5 1/4 September 1838 8.8 9 - 8 8 1/4- 5 3/8 October 1838 10.4 11 1/2- 8 8 1/4- 5 1/8 November 1838 10.5 11 1/2-10 1/4 8 1/2- 5 3/4 December 1838 11.5 12 1/2-11 8 3/4- 6 1/2 January 1839 12.3 12 3/4-11 1/2 9 - 7 3/8 February 1839 12.9 14 -12 8 3/4- 7 1/8 March 1839 13.8 14 1/2-13 1/2 9 3/4- 8 April 1839 14.6 15 -13 1/2 0 - 8 1/2 May 1839 14.4 14 3/4-13 1/2 9 5/8- 7 3/4 June 1839 14.3 14 1/2-11 1/2 9 1/2- 7 3/8 July 1839 12.5 13 -12 7 - 6 August 1839 10.3 13 1/2-10 8 1/2- 6 1/2 September 1839 9.3 10 1/2-10 7 1/2- 6 1/4 October 1839 10.3 10 3/4-10 8 1/2- 6 November 1839 9.3 10 1/2- 8 1/4 7 3/4- 5 3/4 December 1839 7.5 8 1/2- 7 1/4 7 3/4- 6 January 1840 7.9 8 1/2- 7 1/4 6 3/4— 5 1/2 February 1840 7.3 7 3/4- 6 3/4 5 3/4- 5 March 1840 6.5 7 - 6 5 3/4- 5 April 1840 6.8 7 1/4- 6 1/4 5 3/4- 5 May 1840 6.9 7 3/4- 6 1/2 5 1/2— 4 3/4 June 1840 7.5 8 - 7 1/4 6 3/4- 4 1/2 July 1840 7.8 8 - 7 1/2 6 3/4- 5 August 1840 8.3 8 1/2- 7 1/2 6 3/4— 5 September 1840 8.3 9 - 8 6 3/4- 5 October 1840 8.4 9 - 7 3/4 6 3/4- 5 1/4 November 1840 8.3 8 1/2- 8 6 1/2- 5 December 1840 8.4 8 1/2- 8 1/4 6 1/2- 5 January 1841 8.5 9 1/4- 8 1/4 7 1/4- 6 February 1841 9.6 9 3/4- 9 1/4 7 1/4- 6 March 1841 9.6 9 3/4- 9 7 1/4- 6 April 1841 10.0 10 1/4- 9 1/2 7 1/2- 6 1/8 May 1841 10.1 10 1/2-10 7 1/2- 5 5/8 June 1841 9.8 10 - 9 1/4 7 1/4- 5 3/8 July 1841 9.3 9 1/2- 9 7 - 5 1/4 August 1841 9.0 9 1/4- 9 7 - 5 September 1841 8.5 8 1/2- 8 1/4 7 ~ 5 October 1841 8.6 8 3/4— 8 1/4 7 - 5 November 1841 8.6 8 3/4- 8 1/4 6 3/4- 4 3/4 December 1841 8.3 8 3/4- 8 6 3/4- 4 3/4 January 1842 7.9 8 - 7 1/2 February 1842 7.3 7 3/4- 7 1/4 March 1842 7.4 7 1/2- 6 3/4 418 TABLE C-5.--Continued. New Orleans Year and Month (Cents) (Pence) (Pence) Series A Series B England Liverpool April 1842 7.5 7 1/2- 6 3/4 May 1842 6.6 7 - 6 1/4 June 1842 6.6 7 - 6 1/2 July 1842 7.6 7 1/2- 6 1/4 "1" August 1842 6.3 7 - 6 September 1842 7.4 7 1/2- 6 October 1842 6.1 7 - 5 3/4 November 1842 6.0 6 - 5 1/2 December 1842 5.6 6 - 5 1/4 January 1843 5.8 6 - 5 1/4 February 1843 5.2 5 1/2- 5 March 1843 4.9 5 1/4- 4 1/2 April 1843 5.4 5 5/8- 4 7/8 May 1843 6.0 6 1/4- 5 1/2 June 1843 6.0 6 1/4- 5 3/4 July 1843 6.0 6 1/4- 5 3/4 August 1843 6.0 6 1/4- 5 3/4 September 1843 6.6 7 1/2- 5 3/4 October 1843 7.1 7 1/2- 6 3/4 November 1843 7.1 7 3/8- 6 3/4 December 1843 9.0 9 - 7 1/8 January 1844 7.7 9 - 8 1/4 February 1844 7.7 9 1/8- 8 1/4 March 1844 7.8 8 5/8- 7 1/2 April 1844 7 l 8 - 6 3/4 May 1844 7.2 7 3/8- 6 1/2 June 1844 7.1 7 3/8- 6 3/4 July 1844 7.0 7 1/8- 6 1/2 August 1844 7.0 7 - 6 1/4 September 1844 5.8 6 1/4- 6 October 1844 5.8 6 - 5 3/8 November 1844 5.3 5 1/2- 4 7/8 December 1844 5.3 5 1/4- 4 1/2 January 1845 4.7 5 - 4 3/8 n.g. = not given. Sources: Price Series A: Lewis C. Gray, History of Agriculture in the Southern United States to 1860 (Washington: Carnegie Insti- tution, 1933), Vol. II, p. 1027. Price Series B: James E. Boyle, Cotton and the New Orleans Cotton Exchange (Garden City: 1934), pp. 176-178. England: Walter B. Smith, Economic Aspects of the Second Bank of the United States (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1953), p. 190. Liverpool: Journal of the American Institute (March, 1839), p. 131. "TI'II'I‘IIIIIIIZILILIIIflIflIflflIIII'IIIIIIlTIIII'Es