SOME ASPECTS OF OVERHEAD ACCOUNTING FOR INCOME MEASUREMENT AND COST CONTROL BY WILLIAM LEONARD FERRARA A THESIS Submitted to School for Advanced Graduate Studies of Michigan State University of Agriculture and Applied Science in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Financial Administration 1959 ACKNOWLE DGEME NTS The author wishes to express his sincere thanks to Dr. B. C. Lemke for guidance and valuable suggestions, especially in the early stages of this writing. Grateful. acknowledgement is also due to Dr. G. M. Jones who gave unselfishly of his time and made many valuable suggestions. The writer is also indebted to Dr. J. D. Edwards for his advice and continuing aid in facilitating completion of this study. Each of the author's guidance committee members, Drs. R. Simonds, K. Boedecker, T. Standt, and H. Brainard, has made suggestions and contributions for which he is grateful. Special thanks are due to the public and industrial accountants who were kind enough to share some of their knowledge, opinions, practices and experiences with the author. This work is dedicated to my wife, Carol Ann, and my Children, Stephen, Paul, and Janeen Marie who provided the encouragement. the incentive and the devotion necessary to ComPlete th is s tudy . WILLIAM LEONARD FERRARA Candidate for the degree of Doctor of PhilOSOphy Final examination: June 5, 1959, 2 p. m. Dissertation: Some Aspects of Overhead Accounting for Income Measurement and Cost Control Outline of Studies: Degree‘ Major Minor Granted B . S . C Accounting Economics , June, 1952 Industrial Management .M.I\. Accounting Economics March, 1954 Ph . D . Accounting Economics. December, 1959 Finance, Industrial , Management Biograph ica l I terns: Born: September 5, 1930, Chicago, Illinois Undergraduate Studies, De Paul University, 1948-52 graduate Studies, Michigan State University, 1952-1959. Passed Uniform CPA Examination, May, 1953 \ Graduate assistant, Michigan State University, 1952-1955. Junior and Senior Accountant, Harris. Reames, and Ambrose, Certified Public Accountants, Lansing, Michigan, 1955-1957. Instructor, Michigan State University, 1957—1959. Exper-ience: Membership: Beta Alpha Psi American Institute of Certified Public Accountants Illinois Society of Certified Public Accountants American Accounting Association iv SOME ASPECTS OF OVERHEAD ACCOUNTING FOR INCOME MEASUREMENT AND COST CONTROL by WILLIAM LEONARD FERRARA AN ABSTR.CT Submitted to the School for Advanced Graduate Studies of Michigan State University of Agriculture and Applied Science in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Financial Administration U.) 195 Approved William L. Ferrara The income measurement and cost control aspects of accounting for manufacturing overhead costs have yet to be fully developed. Concepts applicable only to other cost finding purposes have been adopted for income measurement. Control of manufacturing overhead costs is viewed as pro— ceeding from ex post analyses of the variances of standard costing and flexible budgeting. Costing concepts historically developed for sales price determination and cost control have been accepted with little, if any, mofidication for income measurement. The normal capacity concept and the idea that unit costs should not be allowed to fluctuate with volume are remnants of the early emphasis on price determination and cost control. Use of the normal capacity concept brought forth the direct costing controversy. Attempts to defend traditional accounting on the basis of a cycle capacity concept or a Practical capacity concept failed to recognize the inherent limitations of all three capacity concepts when they are used to measure income. To measure income properly, overhead should be Categorized and allocated as follows: vi William L. Ferrara Category Bases of Allocation Costs applicable to fixed Units of production or assets (depreciation, insurance an approximation thereto and taxes) which is the cycle capacity concept Indivisible costs inputs or Actual output chunk costs (the semi-variable costs which are absolutely necessary for all outputs within a range of outputs) Other overhead costs Actual output (primarily the costs to Operate fixed assets) The unit of production basis for allocating fixed asset costs isthe only basis consistent with the expected use (useful life) of fixed assets. Allocation of "chunk costs" on the basis of actual output is the only method consistent with the fact that "chunk costs" are absolutely rmcessary'costs for any output within the range that ”chunk cmsts“ can serve. On the above bases unit costs may vary Wiflixnalume and the generally assumed utility of a fixed— variable breakdown for cost allocation is rejected. IVithin the realm of cost control the fact that many mm-of-1jgue conditions can and will be eliminated long before variances are accumulated must be recognized. Control of overhead costs starts with preventive cost control, continues vii William L. Ferrara znth visual observation and ends with variance accumulations. Iueventive cost control attempts to stop waste before it sfiarts. Visual Observation by workers and supervisors stops wane before it starts or as soon as it is detected. Variance cmumulations detect wastes which have evaded visual obser— wfijon and show the profit impact of waste. The traditional approach to cost control is ex post hithat variances are analyzed to determine root causes Vfiuch must be eliminated. Such analyses are not only too lauafOr truly effective cost control; their approach is entirely inappropriate, for they ask the question, what must is £12 3931? (after we find out what went wrong). The only (nestion consistent with the residual position of variance reports is what has already been done? to eliminate the causes of out-of-line performance. viii TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I II. ADAPTATION OF OVERHEAD COSTING TO INCOME MEASUREMENT AND COST CONTROL: A FUNCTIONAL APPROACH TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF OVERHEAD COSTING . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Early Emphasis on price determination and waste elimination . . . . . . . . . 9 The birth of overhead . . . . . . . . . 12 Influence of Price Determination on the Content of Overhead . . . . . . . . . . 17 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Thomas Battersby and overhead . . . . . . 18 The Whitesmiths of Taunton and overhead . 20 The Texts of the '80's and '90's . . . . 22 Literature and practice of the '80's and 90's . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 The Increate of competition: A. Hamilton Church and the content of overhead. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 CHAPTER Rise of cost control and changing sales price ideology . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Rising Influence of Cost Control: A Hamilton Church and His Supplementary Rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Description of the supplementary rate . Limitations of the supplementary rate . The prime critic - John Whitmore . . Church's defense and the demise of a pricing concept . . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Sequel to the Supplementary Rate The ideas of H. L. Gantt . . . . . . . General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Factors Influencing Gantt Sales price determination . . . . Measurement of operating efficiency The social problems concerning labor and capital . . . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . capacity measurement . . . . . . IT“? normal overhead concept . . . . . . . . PAGE 39 42 43 43 46 48 51 55 56 56 59 61 64 65 66 66 (REQTER General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Early literature . . . . . . . . Contemporary literature Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The cYcle overhead concept . . . . . General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Early literature . . . . . . . . . Some early objectors . . . . . . . . . Contemporary literature Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The practical capacity concept . . . . . General . . . . . . . . . . . . . Church, Whitmore, and Gantt and practical capacity . . . . . . . Other writers and practitioners and practical capacity . . . . . . . Some special problems Categories of machines or capacity Categories of idle capacity . . . . Influence of standard costing on capacity measures . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . sumary: The sequel to the supplementary rate . ; . . . . . . . . . . . . PAGE 66 67 71 74 76 76 76 82 84 88 90 90 91 92 94 99 102 104 106 CHAPTER. PAGE Cost Control and the Development of Overhead Costing . . . . . . . . . . . 113 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113 Idle capacity costs and efficiency measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 Standard costing ideology . . . . . . . 116 The responsibility idea . . . . . . . 125 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 Income Measurement and the Development of Overhead Costing . . . . . . . . . . 129 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 Early writings . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 Breakdown of commercial and manufacturing overhead . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 Exclusion of imputed interest from manufacturing overhead . . . . . . . 135 The supplementary rate and its sequel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139 A. Hamilton Church and income measurement 140 Development of overhead allocation . . 141 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 III. INDUSTRIAL OPERATION AND OVERHEAD COSTS: THE VIEWPOINT OF ECONOMICS . . . . . . . 150 PAGE Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 Income measurement and cost control . . . 152 Variable Costs and VOlume variation . . . 154 General I. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154 Statistical cost studies . . . . . . . . 156 Controversy over marginalism . . . . . 158 Fixed Costs and VOlume variation . . . . . 162 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162 Fixed costs and economic waste . . . . 163 Fixed costs and competition . . . . . . 170 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170 Public utility industries . . . . . . 171 Non—public utility industries . . . . 174 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179 IV. INDUSTRIAL OPERATIONS AND OVERHEAD COSTS: THE VIEWPOINT OF MANAGEMENT . . . . . . . 182 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182 Financial Accounting As a Management Tool . 185 Summarized data . . . . . . . . . . . . . 186 Long-run assumption . . . . . . . . . . . 186 Outsider orientation . . . . . . . . . . 188 ,Measure of economic progress . . . . . . 190 CHAPTER PAGE Cost Accounting As a Management Tool . . . 191 Extention of financial accounting . . . 192 Historical costs versus predetermined costs . . . .p. . . . . . . . . . . . 193 Responsibility accounting . . . . . . . 199 Other aspects of cost accounting Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206 Decision making , . . . . . . . . . . 214 Beware of oversimplification . . . . 218 Fixed Overhead Costs and Management . . . 224 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226 V. THE MODERN APPROACH TO OVERHEAD COSTING AND INCOME MEASUREMENT AND THE NEED FOR RECONSIDERATION OF BASIC IDEOLOGICAL \ FOUNDATIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228 Direct Costing: Origins . . . . . . . . . 229 Direct Costing: The Period of Refinement . 235 Early emphasis: eliminate the normal overhead concept . . . . . . . . . . . 235 Switch in emphasis Approach of the economic marginalist . . . . . . . . . . . 238 CWWTER PAGE Approach of the break—even enthusiast . . . . . . . . . . 239 The perfect argument . . . . . . 240 The Case of the Defense . . . . . . . . . 243 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 243 Idle capacity as a defense . . . . . . . 246 Recognizing limitations of marginalism . 253 An Improved Approach . . . . . . . . . . . 259 General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259 Overhead cost segregation for income measurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . 265 Idle capacity costs and income measurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273 Some objecticns considered . . . . . . 286 The misguided marginalist and break- even enthusiast . . . . . . . . . . . 292 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 301 VI. THE MODERN APPROACH TO OVERHEAD COSTING AND COST CONTROL AND THE NEED FOR AN INTEGRATED AND CONTINUOUS APPROACH . . . 304 Traditional Cost Control . . . . . . . . . 304 Operating Controls In The Factory: Physical Standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 308 CHMMER General . . . . . . . . . . . Direct materials . . . . . . . Direct labor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Overhead . . . . . The Integrated and Continuous Approach . Limitations of traditional cost - control . . . . i . . . . . . Limitations of physical standards Hierarchical ranking and the integration of cost and physical standards . . . Illustrations of the Integrated and Continuous Approach . . . . Genera1-. Direct materials Direct labor Overhead . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . \HI. SUMMARY.AND CONCLUSIONS BIBLIOGRAPHY................. PAGE 308 309 312 314 316 316 318 322 332 332 338 351 361 378 383 398 LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS ILLUSTRATION 1. 10. The PrOblen Posed by Fixed Manufacturing Overhead Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . Quantified Illustration of Capacity Concepts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Three Dimensional Break—even Chart . . The Traditional and The Recommended Methods of Allocating Overhead Costs . . . . . Unit of Production Depreciation . . . . . Depreciation Costs Under Normal or Cycle Capacity . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary of Control Over Material Usage Summary of Control Over Labor Usage Summary of Control Over Overhead Costs Summary of Control Over operating Department Overhead Costs Related to the Operation of 'Equipment and Facilities . . . . . . . . PAGE 108 109 257 272 287 288 340 353 363 376 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Manufacturing overhead1 is the source of many accounting problems. The significance of this statement is readily understood when the heterogeneous nature of manufacturing overhead is considered. It is nothing more than a gigantic "catch all" category. Accepted definitions admit this when they state that manufacturing overhead includes all manu— facturing costs except direct labor and direct materials or all those manufacturing costs which cannot be traced to a Particular production order. In other words, manufacturing overhead is neither direct labor nor direct materials, and direct labor and direct materials are those costs which can be traced to a particular production order. Perhaps another disconcerting feature of the "catch all" nature of manufacturing overhead is that the above definition is often modified to inchide all those costs not worth tracing to a particular Pmduction order . K 1 Manufacturing overhead is sometimes referred to as ove . . . . rhead, manufacturing burden, burden, indirect manufacturing expenses’ and even oncost. 2 One factor which has had an ever—increasing tendency micomplicate overhead accounting and also to make it more significant has been the combined relative and absolute in— crease in the amount of manufacturing overhead. This increase has been and will continue to be caused by techno— ]rmical development or automation wherein direct forms of labor are replaced by machinery. Another factor has been the relative increase of fringe benefits in the total wage bill. In both cases a direct or traceable item of manu— ihcturing cost is replaced by an indirect item. In many instances the items causing the relative and absolute increase in.manufacturing overhead are items that do not vary within vdde ranges of production volume. Among the many problems emanating from overhead accounting are two that have received wide attention in recent years. These are the problems related to income measurement and cost control. In the case of income measurement, accountants have not recognized the true rational foundations and origins of cost accounting for overhead costs in general, and for fixed overhead costs in particular. TOO many have unthinkingly adopted for income measurement purposes concepts applicable to other cost finding purposes, or have warped the concepts in such a way (A) that their quantification has questionable utility for cuiginally intended functions or for income measurement pur— poses. Such a situation presents a fundamental challenge to 13m integrity of financial statements. In the case of cost control, especially with regard ‘Uioverhead costs, accountants have never really constructed maintegrated system that illustrates the prOper position of aumounting accumulations. Many have frustrated cost control kmrwrapping it up in the double entry framework. Many others have added to the variance accumulations of double entry such finngs as periodic reports of controllable costs by respon— sibility centers, as well as periodic reports of spoilage, labor efficiency and even machine efficiency. This all seems adequate until it is realized that most of the cost axmumulators and report gatherers visualize control as starting with the report and an analysis of variances between aumual and expected performance. Their point of departure is an intensive analysis of variances in order to determine root causes which must be eliminated. Such a report is not onLy too late for truly effective cost control, but its approach is entirely inappropriate, for it asks the question 'wmat must w; 82 g9w?", after we take the precious time to analyze what went wrong in the first place. The appropriate 4 cumstion is "what has been done?”lto eliminate those factors ghfing rise to out—Of—line performance. This more appropriate question has grown out of the vniter's personal dissatisfaction with the traditional approach to cost control which places too much reliance on adier—the—fact cost accumulations. To be effective, control nmst eliminate out—of-line conditions before they occur or mssoon as possible after they occur. Cost accumulations are guepared too late to be of effective use in cost control. Asvdll be illustrated later, many of the factors giving rise to out-of—line performance can be and are eliminated long before cost data are accumulated. Thus it will be seen that the role of cOst accumulations in a cost control system differs considerably from the assigned role in the traditional amproach to cost control. Cost control will be portrayed as endhng rather than starting with the accumulation of variances between actual and expected costs. 131 conjunction with the above expressed needs the Objectives of this dissertation will be (1) to provide a more reasoned approach to overhead costing and income measurement with special emphasis on the fixed element of overhead cost, and (2) to present a meaningful approach to the position caf overhead cost accumulations in a cost control system. These objectives may seem somewhat unrelated, but as vullbe shown they are tightly interwoven in terms of their rusunjcal development as well as their theoretical and prmfifical application. They are, in effect, hardly separable. Source data for this study includes the rather large sane Of literature included in such publications as the lhtnxml Association of Cost Accountants Yearbooks and fififletins, The Journal of Accountancy and The Accounting flgflgw. Particularly appropriate literature in the fields Ofifinancial and production management as well as economics hasalso been considered. In addition, in order to add the fnushing touch of current applications, the writer's limited emmmience in the field of public accounting has been buiressed by interviews with outstanding practitioners hlprofessional accounting as well as by some interviews with fidustrial accountants. FOllowing this introduction, there will be six mkhtional chapters. In Chapter Two the adaptation of (nerhead costing to the purposes of income measurement and cost control will be considered. In effect, this will be a hummional approach to the development of overhead costing iflUch will attempt to illustrate the major factors in— fluencing the growth and refinements in overhead costing. 6 Among the major factors to be covered will be the influence of price determination and efficiency measures On overhead costing, the very significant contributions of Alexander Hamilton Church and their ultimate development into the measures of wasted and utilized capacity as well as standard costing. All of this material will then be related to in— come measurement, cost control and the development of overhead costing. Chapters Three and Four will cover the significant implications of industrial operations and overhead costs from the viewpoints of economics and management. These Pages on economics in and of themselves have great Significance, especially in light of some current ideas con— cerning the accountant's concepts of income measurement as they are related to overhead costing. A pragmatic approach is the essence of the chapter on management's point of view. The utility of both financial and cost accounting is con— sidered with special emphasis on overhead costing. In the light of these exploratory chapters, chapter Five will consider the modern approach to overhead costing and income measurement as well as related controversies. This will be terminated with a more reasoned approach to in- come measurement which will recognize the true rational foundations of the conflicting ideologies. Chapter Six will consider the modern approach to overhead costing and cost control, and its limitations. This will be terminated with an attempt to put forth a reasoned analysis of the function and place of cost accumulations in cost control, particularly overhead cost control. Chapter Seven will summarize this study, “Some Aspects of Overhead Accounting For Income Measurement and Cost Control, " with a, restatement of significant factors and present certain conclusions that seem justified by the study. These conclusions will have definite implications for public, industrial and academic accountants. CHAPTER II ADAPTATION OF OVERHEAD COSTING TO INCOME MEASUREMENT AND COST CONTROL: A FUNCTIONAL APPROACH TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF OVERHEAD COSTING* Introduction General Cost accounting, like many other fields of endeavor, evolved to meet felt needs. This is especially true of cost accounting development in the period of most active industrial growth, that is, around the turn of the nineteenth century. It is even more true of accounting for overhead costs, which only began to assume importance in the latter part of the nineteenth century . tMany ofothe items to be discussed in this chapter anacovered in more detail by S. Paul Garner, Evolution_gf .Q§$.Accounting:£g 1925 (Tuscaloosa, Alabama: University of Ahmama Press, l954),4l6 pp. and David Solomons "The Historical Development of Costing" in David Solomons (ed.) §3§udies _j_._n Costing (London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952), 1:52, inlooth cases the approach is much different from that taken here. Garner seems to take as his point of departure income measurement while Solomons seems to emphasize a densiOn—nuflthe determination of selling prices. Manufacturers vmreinterested primarily in direct material and labor cost. Ownmead was considered only in terms of that broad per- cmfiage Which, when added to direct costs, was to yield the ssUing price or "hoped for” selling price. Ordinarily there wasno distinction made between the various elements of ownhead. .Manufacturing overhead, commercial overhead, and "mxmd for" profits were all lumped together in one per- centage figure.l4 Increasingly competitive conditions in industry resumed a more scientific method of price determination. thmms and practitioners began to draw a distinction between ““eTnies of overhead and also to discuss refinements in Umxmflhods of allocating overhead to production. As competitive pressures increased there came to be a gradual shift or blending of price determination and cost ccmimlin overhead costing. Overhead costing came to be k 14 . Garner, 0 . c1t., 122. 18 :mflated to more scientific allocation schemes intent on lnnlding up selling prices and measures of manufacturing effnflency. The following pages are designed to illustrate theemrly influence of price determination on the content of overhead . Thomas Battersby and Overhead In his discussion of a text written by Thomas BaUmmsby in 1878,15 Professor Garner, without any apparent inUHWion of stressing the point, illustrated quite clearly thatsales price determination was the paramount consideration incwerhead allocation.l6 Garner discussed the six different‘ medmfls of costing Battersby had seen used in his public acmxmting practice. In none of the methods was a dis— thmtnxxmade between manufacturing overhead and selling andadministrative overhead. The relevant remarks classified according to the mnhmiused are as follows (italics all mine): (1). . . Twenty-five percent of the preceding total was added on for profit, as well as 25% profit on all _.-‘~_______. 15 Thomas Battersby, The Perfect Double Entry Bookkeeper, (Manchester: 1878) 6 Garner, op. cit., 70-76. 19 materials used. To the total Battersby added the cost of materials in order to arrive at the sellipg price. (2). . . Then 25 percent of the total was added on for indirect expenses and profit, as well as the usual 25 percent for profit on materials purchased. All these sums plus the cost of the materials used gave the selling_price. (3) . . . In the third method the wages paid to workers were added to a percentage of wages for the use of tools and other expenses. To this total was added the profit to arrive at the selling_prige. (4) . . . In the fourth method all the tools were rated according to the purchase price and the power required to work them, plus the workman's wages, and every workman is rated at the wages paid him, apd a_percentage for indirect expense and_prg§it is addpd on the total and on materials purchased, whigh gives the sellingdprice. (5) . . . The fifth method was purely arbitrary. A so-called 'rate' was fixed by some responsible person in the organization based upon the purchase price of the tools and lathes used. These rates then were 'used as selling prices, both for contract work and jobbing work.‘ I (6) . . . The sixth method was used where piecework was employed. The total cost of materials was added to the piece—rate wages paid to employees. Then a percentage was added for the use of tools as well as minor charges. Onto this total anotherppercentage was added for theprofit.l7 In criticizing these methods, Battersby said, in afikct, that the rates used were based on opinion and assumption, and their advocates "hoped that the percentages l7fi1xid,,taken from Thomas Battersby, op. cit.,34. 2O amirates employed would be sufficient to cover the overhead 18 After his criticism Battersby itamaand a profit as well." remmmmnded his own method, about which Garner said, "These data [prime costs] were in turn to be transferred to a pnnmte cost ledger where certain percentages for overhead dmrmfisand profits were to be added on, giving the selling pnue and gross profit on each job.”19 There is no denying that Battersby made some con— trflnmion to the literature and practice of allocating cweflmed costs, but his goal was not inventory valuation. Hissnml was price determination, as was also true of the meflmfis he criticized. The Whitesmiths of Taunton and Overhead In a study of early New England silverware pro— chmtnxflo the same conclusions can be reached regarding the emmumis on price determination. The study of Reed and x 18 Garner, op. cit., 72. 19Ibid., 73. 20 . George S. Gibb, The Whitesmiths 9}: W, A EEEEEX pf Reed and Barton. 1824-1943 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1943) 419 PP. 21 Barflx1by George S. Gibb is quite informative in this mmpafi; When discussing the company's price policy from 1837to 1859 Gibb wrote as follows: In general, the pricing practice followed by the company consisted of a rule—of-thumb policy, having reference on the one hand to direct costs of manufacture, and on the other to the bargaining position of the buyer.21 In other words, overhead costs were to be included in vmaUnmr percentage above the direct costs of manufacture (mannials and labor) the company could bargain out of its cmsUmmrs. The bargaining position of the company was usu- alhzvery good, since it sold highly popular branded merchandise . In the discussion of accounting procedures in the Petkfl from 1860 to 1900, the connection between cost acunmting and price determination is brought out in a very 1MCidmanner. Gibb described the relevant procedures as fOllows: , To the intense annoyance of his salesmen and some of the foremen, George Brabrook, who supervised the costing, habitually placed a value on the metal used far above either the current market price or the price the company had paid for it. The inflated cost resulting from such a practice, Brabrook felt was an excellent cushion against the inevitable cuts 21 Ibid., 159. 22 in the price of the finished article forced on him by the company salesmen and competitive action. Gibb added that in order to arrive at a selling price whnflicovered direct costs, overhead and profit, Brabrook vmuhitake the prime or direct cost of an article and double it. Furthermore Brabrook considered manufacturing overhead, amiadministrative and selling costs as one composite called overhead.23 The Texts of the '80's and '90's As to the latter part of the nineteenth century, A.CL Littleton stated that there were three notable books , 24 . onaSlzed item 6. The mixture of these items (4, 5, and 6) dimvt.seem to bother Church and it is not too difficult to fimne out why. All of them (4, 5, and 6) involve efficiency O3r9fficient utilization of capacity and in a true sense rePI'ESent a "barometer of conditions“in the shop which ought tote separated from other shop costs. Many people today \— 71 lbid., 81. 72 Ibid., 80. 48 wouhilike to break down these portions of the supplementary raUainto a volume variance and an efficiency variance, but munch was content with the combination, although he admitted that analysis of the combination might be useful. In the new method, the state of trade or the general efficiency of management affect the supplementary rate alone, and a similar cost at two different periods might, if analyzed, show that what had been gained in method had been neutralized by a fall in the volume of trade by a muddled condition of shOp organization. or ’73 Mr. Church did not mention items 1, 2, and 3, above eidun because he didn't recognize them as problems, or he feh:that their effect if any, would be immaterial. O The Prime Critic—~John Whitmore The supplementary rate was well received as a real mhmnce in the field of costing, but Church had one major crude. John Whitmore took Church to task, not for isolating theidle and misused capacity, but for taking this element amiallocating it to production. Church and Whitmore appear tolmve been in agreement as to the major purpose of their effints, i. e., the identification and elimination of waste. mWrst position in this respect was described fully in the lastsection of this study; as for Whitmore's similar K 73 Ibid., 81. 49 position, it was stated as follows: The fundamental principle is always the same namely, the principle of making a record sufficiently full to constitute a clear accounting for the factory expenditure; and the object of the accounts is always the same, namely, to eliminate waste from the operations. This then may be said to be the purpose of all factory accounting: to produce records in which waste shall be plainly shown as waste. Both Whitmore and Church were essentially in mneement on the content of the supplementary rate with one WUOI exception. Whitmore wanted to consider only idle capacity; He did not want to include in his cost of idle caPacity'the so-called truly general overhead which could notsensibly be associated with individual production cen- ters. Iflost important of all, Whitmore wanted to put the lumts<3f idle capacity in a separate and conspicuous account VTactory Capacity Idle"L and to treat this account as an ex ens - - ' 75 P e or loss in the period it was accumulated. Treating idle capacity costs as a loss is the real dtfikrence between the positions of Church and Whitmore. CWHTh Used the idle capacity costs plus the truly general .\\——— Ma1y John Whitmore, "Factory Accounting As Applied to 24: me Sh°PS'" The Journal 91:: Accountancy. 11 (August, 1906), 75 Ibid., 257 and 31. .w flufiuilflzl SO cwerhead as the subject of the supplementary rate which allocated idle capacity costs to production. With Whitmore tmere was no supplementary rate, but only a dollar amount of Nile capacity costs which Whitmore wanted to treat as a losszrather than a part of product cost. Whitmore actually made quite clear the reasons for Ins difference of opinion when he praised Church's scientific rmmhine rate for leading to the exact statement of unused cmmcity; Specific identification of unused capacity, mebelieved, would lead ultimately to the utilization of flum capacity by bringing into play two forces, viz., EU reiieving cost prices of a burden that does not belong to them, thereby creating better con— ditions commercially” E4 and next by bringing into plain view the cost of idle factory capacity, and making it possible to trace its causes and to fix responsibility for it and to secure earnest and well-directed “efforts to remedy fig76 ‘ f Whitmore's reasons, then, for isolating the cost of 1dlecaPacity were to direct attention to it so that the pHXESSeS tending toward its elimination might be instituted, as“ell as to remove it from those cost figures used to e . . . Standsh selling prices. Church and Whitmore agreed on the \— 7 6Ibid., 258. 51 primacy of waste elimination as such, but disagreed as to its implementation. Whitmore's insistence on a unit cost free of.ndle capacity costs was a turning point in the use of cost figures for price determination purposes. I Churrh's Defense and The Demise of A Pricing Concept In 1910 Church tried to defend his supplementary rate, stating that idle capacity costs were distributed ld selling price principle that all costs had to be recovered or included in selling prices, it is interesting u>note that Whitmore used sales price determination as one dfhis reasons for not spreading idle capacity costs over Pmflucts. It is hard to imagine any other explanation for nus statement: This it does first by relieving cost prices of a burden that does not belong to them, thereby 86 creating immediately a better condition commercially. N this change in view on the part of Church as basically asample matter involving the double entry framework wherein thesubJect of the supplementary rate becomes a cost of pro— dm“3(a balance sheet item) or a loss (an income statement item . 85 d . A. Hamilton Church, “Overhead——The Cost of Pro— fixilon Preparedness," Factory and Industrial Management, XXXI (January,1931), 4o. 86 She Whitmore, "Factory Accounting As Applied to Machine 1:33.93. _c_i_t_., 258. Garner (92. gi_t_., 219) and Brummet $L£m2£§., 19) both seem to be under the impression that pan;0re agreed with Church in making idle capacity cost a of product costs via the supplementary rate. '~ .v 55 Whitmore thus was one of the first, if not the first, to consider elimination of idle capacity from product costs on thelaasis of its inapplicability to the determination of a fair and commercially feasible price. Summary The ”supplementary rate“ of Alexander Hamilton Church flmused attention on the problems of idle capacity costs, evmiiflnough Church's supplementary rate included costs odmr than idle capacity costs. The major use of the ”rate" mas as a "barometer of efficiency" in that changes in the 'Tate" supposedly indicated similar changes in efficiency. Actually, the "rate" was a very crude measure of efficiency at best in that there were a number of factors, hmluding commercial efficiency (sales volume) and technical Efffiflency, that could occur in an infinite number of combi— naflflnS. When Whitmore came along, he pointed out that he wasinterested only in the costs of idle capacity. He ‘nfihEd to show this waste as waste in order that steps might betaken to eliminate it. Whitmore then, changed the 'banmfiter—of—efficiency" idea to a dollar measure of waste. In order to show the waste more clearly Whitmore d' . Minot want to allocate it to production (via the supplementary rate). nor in addition, did he want the waste to be included in product costs used as a basis for price determination. This idea was fundamentally new and showed clearly a change frmn a system wherein all costs were utilized to build up selling prices, to a system which emphasized an efficient cost, without such waste, as the foundation of a fair and cmmmarcially feasible price. Whitmore's idea of costs for sales price determination is quite prominent in the overhead mmemes usually associated with H. L. Gantt and many others. 'flm next section will consider these concepts in detail. The Sequel to the Supplementary Rate The Ideas of H. L. Gantt Genera 1 Church‘s supplementary rate not only stirred up a sneat deal of controversy, but it also shifted a number of paxfle into new lines of thought concerning the treatment Ofidle capacity costs. Idle capacity came to be considered asa-measure of unutilized fixed costs of equipment and its Inkeep, or else as a measure of unutilized overhead costs, asamung that only variable overhead costs vary directly WithProduction, which is in effect the same idea. Prominent among these people was H. L. Gantt, who 57 in 1915 expressed the opinion that: When a plan is operating at less than its full capacity, it is quite evident that the expense of maintaining a certain portion of the plant in idleness must be borne somehow. The old theory that it must be borne as a part of the cost of the articles produced is rapidly giving way to the theory that it is a business expense and not chargeable to the articles pro— duced. In the same year he stated his general principle CWKEIrning the relation between production and fixed costs- The indirect expense chargeable to the out— put of a factory bears the same ratio to the indirect expense necessary to run the factory at normal capacity, as the output in question bears to the normal output of the factory. Gantt was certainly not the first one to express fimse \uews, but he was undoubtedly the best—known and most hkely'to be listened to in business circles at that time. .Rmn MHUtmore actually expressed Gantt's general principle hil906, when he quantified idle time in terms of the (hiference between the time each machine was used and the tmm or hours used to measure the capacity of each machine. \fi. 87 Ifibf't 'H. L. Gantt, "The Effect of Idle Time on Costs and 80.1 S.’ Annals g; the American Academy Q: Politigal and ~$flfli Science, xLI (September, 1915), 87. 88 . (kmts " H. L. Gantt, "The Relation Between Production and ' Transactions 9f the American Society of Meghgnigal rs. XXXVII (June, 1915 Meeting) 112. En inee firJ .. f w. -. 58 The idle time was multipled by the machine rate and, in effect, produced the same answer Gantt did for the cost of idle capacity.89 In 1908 P. J. Darlington expressed the same thought when he emphasized the expense character of idle capacity costs. C. H. Scovell, in an article published in 1914, agreed'Wholeheartedly, He believed the scientific machine hour rate was the greatest coSting advance in a generation since it yielded more precision in burden accounting, in addition to having the ability to make an "accurate measure" of loss due to slack production or interrupted operation.91 An interesting side—issue at this point is that (mutt apparently had not developed this point of view in his earlier years. In 1897 at the annual meeting of the Mmuican Society of Mechanical Engineers Gantt made no men— tnxiof the issue of idle time in a discussion of a Sumation in which it most certainly fitted, that is, how to \fi— 89 Whitmore, 92. cit., 28. 90 P. J. Darlington, "The Fundamental Principles of 2:11;“ Organization and Management, " The Engineering Magazine: V (April, 1908). 65. Clinton H. Scovell, "Cost Accounting Practice With Acmg Reference to the Machine Hour Rate," The Journal 9: M. XVII (January, 1914), 13-27. Special 59 set a burden rate fOr a tool running only one tenth of the time.92 Factors Influencing Gantt: Sales Price Determination Mr. Gantt and his contemporaries seem to have been influenced in their ideas by three considerations: 1. The necessity for arriving at selling prices. 2. PrOblems concerning the measurement of operating efficiency. 3. The social prdblems concerning labor and capital. In 1915 Mr. Gantt criticized the widely-held view 'what the product of a factory, however small, must bear ..93 . . Hm total expense, however large, as being responSIble flu much of the confusion about costs which led to unsound luminess policies. The fact that he was referring to Enicing decisions was made quite clear when he said Our cost systems, as generally operated at present, show under such conditions that our ‘costs are high and, if business is very bad, they usually show us a cost far greater than the amount we can get for the goods. In other words, our present systems of cost acggunting go to pieces When they are most needed. \\ 92 Lane, 99. cit., 897. 93 C H. L. Gantt, "The Relation Between Production and Osts," 5&3. ci ., 113.’ 94 l2;g.. 110 60 Sir Arthur Lowes Dickinson, eminent English accountant, was also concerned about the then prevailing point of view when he wrote that idle capacity costs must be provided for, but that it would be better to charge them to profit and loss in order not to inflate product costs which might lead to further restriction of production ". . .on the ground that product can no longer be sold at a profit."95 All of these men seemed to be aiming to destroy the concept described by Alexander Hamilton Church in his earlier years (and later abandoned) as one of the most serious canons of "modern theory and practice", that is, vmatever else is done, "every dollar 92 charges must be 96 Efiflened onto some item of work." There is also very little dmmt that Mr. Church's final capitulation to the new view97 wmsan indication of his inability to withstand the more fimceful arguments of his contemporaries. It is interesting to note, again, that Church used hisidea of absorbing idle capacity costs in products to \— 95 amiAb Sir Arthur Lowes Dickinson, "The Construction, Use, use of Cost Accounts," The Journal 9; Accountancy, m" (July. 1927), 10. 96 See Footnote 78. 97 ' See FootnotesB4 and 85. 61 promote the sales price doctrine of his youth, that is, sales must cover all costs. On the other hand, Gantt and the others considered in this section used the idea of a profit and loss charge for unused capacity costs to determine a fairer and more realistically competitive price. This change should pinpoint one major effect of competition on cost accounting theory and practice, that is, the change from full cost pricing to compétitive cost pricing. Factors Influencing Gantt: Measurement of Operating Efficiengy The View of overhead which emphasizes the measurement Cfi'operational efficiency is an outgrowth of the "scientific management" movement. In this case the treatment of idle facility costs is exactly the same as when a competitive Fmice setting standard is paramount. Only the basic purpose Inderlying the treatment is different. Gantt published his bem:statement on idle facility cosfisand measuring operating eflfi£iency only a few years after the articles quoted in the anmeding section. To him, production costs should vary mfly aS‘methods. wages, cost of raw materials and efficiency ofc’Peration change. Costs of production should be separated f . romcaPltal charges, special repairs, and cost f idle m. "Under such conditions, with a definite method and 62 known wage rates and cost of raw materials, the cost of the manufactured article is an indication of the efficiency with vflflch the methodsof manufacture were operated."98 G. Charter Harrison agreed when in 1919, he said that combining the costs of production and the costs of idleness ". . .absolutely kills the value of cost statements considered as indices of Operating efficiencyfl9 An earlier similar statement by William E. McHenry is so revealing that it must be quoted. McHenry wrote that ordinary cost systems are: a combined result of the cost of doing those things which they ought 39 have done, plus the cost of doing those things which they ought g9; 39 hgyg done, and worse still, with algég mixture of the cost 2: not doing anything!!! ‘ Gantt and Harrison are quite clear in their desire to EseParate idle facility costs from other manufacturing costs hlorder to utilize the actual costs of manufacturing as a I“erasure of operating efficiency. Thereby it is possible to \— 98 H. O. Gantt, "The Basis of Manufacturing Costs," lEEEEEIQI Management, LIII (June, 1917), 369. 99 I d G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting in the 'New nrmtrial Day'," Industrial Management. LVIII (December, 1919). 443 100 The William E. McHenry, "Is Your Cost System Scientific,” W Magazine, LI (August, 1916), 678. c. ’ 63 compare the actual costs of producing units in one period with snnilar costs in another period in order to see if progress has or has not been made. On the other hand, McHenry, even though stressing idle facility costs, seemed to want to go further and break the actual costs of manu— facturing into costs that were prOperly incurred and costs that were improperly incurred, i. e., the costs of inefficiency or waste in production. One point is clear, though; all of these men were interested in having idle capacity costs identified very plainly so that managerial attention would be directed toward a large item of expense that should and could be reduced. Church was essentially in agreement with these men in trYing to measure efficiency. The major difference was that munch combined in one category the costs of idle capacity, mmm of the costs of manufacturing inefficiencies (he did run consider that machine hours could be saved or wasted),- amithe general overhead, but he admitted that breakdowns ofthe supplementary rate would be fruitful.101 There is no dmflt that these men added to the structure for which Church lanithe Cornerstone. ai~§__________ 101 . See Footnote 74. 64 Factors Influencing Gantt: The Social Problems Concerning Labor and Capital The last consideration which influenced Mr. Gantt was the social prdblem concerning labor and capital. He believed idle plant was an executive—caused waste and, like idle labor, did not deserve to be paid for by the consumer. The loading of idle plant costs on products produced he felt to be fundamentally false. "It is based on the theory that invested money must return profit, or interest, whether it is used productively or not."102 Mr. Gantt further mentioned his fear about the rapidly rising industrial unrest and said: It is on this account that I say that a recognitioncfifthe expense of idleness and the allocation of this expense to those who are regponsible for it, is the most important economic fact that has been brought to the gttention of the business world for many years.103 Problems concerning the conflict between labor and Capital seem to permeate Mr. Gantt's cost accounting dis— mumions. Perhaps all of his conclusions on idle facility ____‘__________ 10 th 2H. L. Gantt, "Influence of Executives," Annals gf \e mail My g_f_ Political and Social Science, (September, 1919), 259. 103 Ibid., 262. ‘7 65 costs were the result of the labor-capital conflict. Illustrative of Gantt's concern about these social issues are his concluding remarks to the American Society of NEchanical Engineers on the subject of "Production and Costs". This address in 1915 was Mr. Gantt's first on the subject of idle facility costs. He concluded that all efforts should be directed towards worthwhile or beneficial actions to help promote industrial tranquility.104 He added, with specific reference to cost accounting: a combination of properly directed efficiency and proper cost methods are absolutely essential to the solution of our industrial problems, and the hopeful thing about the newer ideas of cost keeping is that they point the way of measuring not only the efficiency of the workman but that of the manager and of the financier.105 $mmary Gantt's ideas have come down to the present day in two major fonns. The first group includes those factors which Camern measures of operating efficiency, and waste identi— fnmtion and elimination. This group will be considered laufl'in this chapter under the title, "Cost Control and fluaDevelopment of Overhead Costing." The second group X 104 ' . CO H H. L. Gantt. "The Relation Between Production and Sts' 92. c t., 128. 10 lbid. . -—-¥"-' ' 66 includes those factors concerning the measurement of capacity which is the key to the determination of utilized and unutilized capacity for purposes of income measurement. Capacity measure- ment is to be considered in the next section of this chapter. Capacity Measurement The methods of meaSuring capacity, for segregating utilized and unutilized capacity costs, fall into three categories: (1) the normal overhead concept——based fundamentally on selling price ideology. - (2) the cycle overhead concept——based on the selling Price idea of the normal overhead concept and some added features of income measurement. ‘7 (3) the practical capacity concept——based on the or{ginal capacity ideas of Church, Whitmore, and Gantt-— whN31 yields the idle capacity measure in its purest form. The last two seem to be the minority.poSitions, and Hwy Will be treated as exceptions to the more prevalent rlonmal overhead concept" in the f01lowing pages. The Normal Overhead Concept Ge 46.er The normal overhead concept is an outgrowth of the Sel' llng Price ideology, which states in effect that the 67 cost of idle capacity should not be included in those cost figures utilized as the foundation of selling prices. Another influence on overhead theorizing which seems to have been quite important was the incidence of depression. The writings on the normal overhead concept were quite prominent in the early 1920's and again during the 1930's, a time when the spectre of depression hovered like a grey shadow over the United States and most of the international commercial world. Early Literature C. B. Williams recognized all of these influences in two appropriately-titled articles published in 1921.106 He shmmed how the abnormal year 1920 pointed up the problem of "h§Posing of overhead during below—normal production, and advOcatedthat the business cycle be used as the basis for €u10cating overhead by defining "normal period" as including a cmmplete cycle of normal, below normal, and above normal mmivity. He believed that doing this would result in an hmmme statement showing normal profits plus or minus over- or . . . . under-capaCIty gains or losses. Williams also considered an! .' _ ‘ Cycle treatment of overhead, pOInting out the limitations \— 1065 See Footnotes 107 and 108. ___1' 68 of months and years as accounting periods, and the possibility in some circumstances of treating an underabsorbed overhead as a deferred charge to be offset by overabsorbed overhead in future periods. He did not make any mention of deferred credit treatment for gyggabsorbed overhead.107 In his second article, six months later, Williams dropped the cycle concept: instead he spoke of "true cost" as the cost obtained under a normal volume of production Which considered quite specifically under—and over—normal Production. Underabsorbed overhead produced a special idle caPacity expense, while overabsorbed overhead produced a Special gain derived from more intensive use of fixed cost inPuts. Williams then completed the normal overhead concept Pattern by invoking the normal cost concept and its relation to lorig—term pricing as a major advantage.108 In 1922 Stanley Fitch presented the same conclusions ' . 109 . mtWO articles. Jordan and Harris also agreed, in their \—. 107 mxmi .C. B Williams, "Treatment of Overhead When Pro— OH 18 Below Normal," The Journal 9; Accountancy, XXXI WY: 1921), 336—42. 108 . . ‘erh1 C. B. Williams, "Treatment of Costs During Periods of 9 volumes of Production," The_gournal of Accountancy, II (November, 1921), 321-33. '— 9 Stanley CL H. Fitch, "Deflation in Relation to Cost ACCOunt in u g, The Journal of Accountancy, XXXIII (January, 1922), l~ll, ._____.__ ___ I .____.. 4 69 text published in 1920. Burden rates should be standard or normal, 1. e., they should bebased on burden costs which occur when production is standard or normal. Furthermore proper selling prices cannot be fixed without standard burden rates. The price, no doubt, would be too high or too low. The use of a standard or average rate, however, is 110 equitable for both estimating and cost purposes. In 1925, at the Annual Meeting of the National Asmociation of Cost Accountants, a vote was taken of favored Hmthods of determining capacity for purposes of overhead allocation. Of the 59 people in attendance, 50 were in favor CK capacity determined on the basis of a cycle of sales fbrecasts so that all burden would be absorbed over the CYcle. Those voting admitted that they would be including, lmder their suggestion, the costs of idleness in product costs. and they used to support their opinions the argu— Hmnts (usual at that time) for sales price determination. Eflght participants were in favor of using a practical erating capacity, that is, maximum theoretical capacity Imnus estimated unavoidable delays. \ Mnm Stanley G. H. Fitch,'"Present-day PrOblems in Industrial I‘louhting," The Journal gf Accountancy, XXXIV (July. 1922). 110 \I. - . (New York. P. Jordon and Gould L. Harris, Cost Accounting The Ronald Press Co., 1920), 222. 70 Only one person voted for the use of expected actual pro— duction for the year for purposes of allocating overhead.lll During the 1930's, another depression period, the same use of a normal capacity concept was considered, with a special tiein to the long-run average basic price. J. H. March wrote that one of the foremost objectives of standard costs was to indicate a normal cost as a guide in setting sales prices.112 Wyman P. Fiske in effect agreed with this, for he stated that normal idle time (seasonal and cyclical) should be included in product costs. He based his conclusions on the "economic principle of normal prices" and held that prices must include normal idleness in order t0 insure business continuity.113 Charles Reitel also agreed when he wrote: In other words, our expected normal capacity should be an interpretation of our sales over quite a long-time: trend, and if our sales expectancy represents 80 per cent or 75 per cent of our plant capacity, I vote for that rather than the maximum 3 .‘__________*__ 1 “1 Discussion, "Some Debatable Points in Cost Accounting eonYo",§ational Association pf Cost Accountants'Yearbook, £225. 187-3, Shall {1:2 H. March, "In Establishing The Budget for Burden DWERe Ornm_' CapaCIty Be Set For Each Department by 1) Giving OutRegar'd to the Capacities of Related Departments; or 2) With- attmegzrxi to Other Departments; or 3) With All Departments Set Accountaame Arbitrary Level?, " National Association 9; Cost ~“‘*~~5!E§'Yearbook 1946, 176. 13 “UNman P. Fiske, "Accounting for Unused Facilit , 3 N'A-C M-Aulletin, XIII. Sec. 1. (November 15. 1931) ¥ ies", 63. 71 plant capacity as Set up by our equipment and our buiidings.1l4 Finally, C. E. Knoeppel, a contemporary of most of the authorities thus far mentioned, was quite lucid about how sales price determination was the key to the normal overhead concept when he wrote: The idea behind this device at that time “Esthat a true cost from which a really competitive price could be determined would be at a normal or average use of the plant facilities, and that any variations in volume above or below this normal or average point influenced the profit and loss account and not the cost of theproduct.115 antemporary Literature The idea of normal capacity which caught on in de- pression periods has come down even to the present day, as is indicated by the following comments. Ellis Sowell, in his doctoral dissertation, concluded that‘tnormal capacity was the predominant capacity measure at . 116 He the he completed his study (1944). Major sources 114 Charles Reitell, "The Standard Cost Plan for the Saca Company," National Association g: Cost Accountants'Year— 4¥$:£22l, 43. 115 Prof‘ C. E Knoeppel and Edgar E. Seybold, Managjngrfnr -ei£ (Neerbrk: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1937), 176. 116 and -Ellis Mast Sowell, The Evolution 9f the Theories \ “HM g_f_ Standard Costs, Unpublished Ph.D. disser— n, The University of Texas, 1944, 294. 9 72 of data leading him to this conclusion were two studies conducted.by the National Association of Cost Accountants. In both cases normal capacity was the predominant capacity measure among over four hundred companies contacted.117 The emphasis on cost and long—run selling prices hung on persistently. In 1944 L. W. Downie stated; Cost estimates are normally the foundation of selling prices and unless normal capacity is used as as basis, the price structure must necessarily be on a false foundation that will tend eventually to des— troy industry. At the 1946 annual meeting of the National Association CE Cost Accountants, H. T. McAnly came to the same con— . 119 , . cluelon. Verne Breitenbucher at the 1946 meeting also agreed; he related the normal capacity idea to a business CYcle and said the fixed element of overhead costs should be absorbed on the basis of "this average normal or standard 117 N.A.C.A. Research Study "Practice in Applying Over— lmad and.Calculating Normal Capacity," N.A.C.A. Bulletin XIX. Sec. 3.(April 1, 1938), 917-32. ' N.A.C.A. Research Study, "Accounting for Excess Labor Costs and Overhead Under Conditions of Increased Pro- 1:221:11". n,A,C,A. Bulletin, XXII, Sec. 3. (August 15, 1941), 118 L. W. Downie, "Normal Capacity and Its Uses", N. M. Bulletin’XXVI, Sec. l.(September 1, 1944), 5. 1419 FOrI> . H. T. McAnly, "Putting Cost Accounting to Work—— ASSOCFOff-t Determination and Inventory Valuation," National 111.3333122 22 Cost Accountants'Yearbook 1946, 133. 73 volume," and his reason for saying this seemed to be ". ..no company can expect to recover in the selling price the excess cost due to the retention of idle capacity."120 The 1948 standard cost research series of the National Association of Cost Accountants shows without doubt that the normal overhead concept was predominant in a study of 72 industrial concerns. This predominance was revealed in the following quotation from the National Association of Cost Accountants published study report. The Standard overhead rate is usually based upon a volume of production which is intended to provide for recovery of overhead costs over a period of years. Used for costing production it avoids the disturbing effect of fluctuations in production volume which tend to increase unit costs in periods of low activity and to decrease unit costs in periods of high activity. T. R. Torian, writing in 1951, also was in favor of the.norhe1 capacity concept which he defined as the level of Mfiivity whidh, over a long period of time, tends to effect abalance between production and sales. "It serves as a X 120 Wolt Verne Breitenbucher, "Putting Cost Accounting to I“"F‘OI‘Cost Control,” National Association 9; Cost W‘ Yearbook 1946, 105. 121 Yoflp 52— §E§£QE£Q.QQ§E§ Are Being Used Currently (New . Natiional Association of Cost Accountants, 1950), 60. Lg! 74 measure of the general activity level which has been, or is expected to be, the average or norm for the company."122 Summary Even though the normal capacity concept had its roots in the "supplementary rate”, it involves a decidedly different point of view. The supplementary rate had as its objective the measurement of waste or inefficiency. The same objective led to the modifications of John Whitmore, H. L. Gantt, and others. The capacity measure utilized was a theoretical meimum.with or-without allowances for unavoidable delays. In such cases, especially where allowances for unavoidable deLays were made, a fairly accurate measure of idle capacity was Obtained. In addition, according to Whitmore and Gantt, sales prices were to be based only on capacity actually IKilized, a factor which both of these men considered quite in1POrtant. The normal capacity approach does not yield a measure QEidle capacity and it is based on a long-run average basic Rfice COncept. The reasoning behind this seems to be wrapped “Pin a depression psychology, wherein the cost figures ut" ilizeci for long-range pricing are not to be influenced by \— 122 f0r1; Thomas R. Torian, "Measuring Activity and Capacity 161, he Buclget," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII. Sec. l.(October, 1951), the seasonal or cyclical nature of business conditions. Normal capacity treatment doesn't yield a measure of idle capacity, since it is based on a policy wherein all over— head is to be recovered in selling prices over a long period of time. In such a case the difference between utilized capacity and normal capacity represents either costs re- covered in this period and not to be recovered in the future haverabsorbed fixed overhead), or costs not recovered in this period which are to be recovered in future periods huuierabsorbed fixed burden). This is not admitted by the abnocates of normal capacity, except insofar as they admit that11a basic long—run average selling price is the key to their’.normal capacity concept. Most of the advocates of noI‘ma]. capacity like to think of over— or under-absorbed tmrden as a special gain or loss due to volume being in amass; of or less than normal. It is unfortunate that this '13 truee, for it presents a situation wherein academic and pr-‘."‘3tiC=ing accountants do not understand the true rational fimmdathDns and practical implications of some of their aMflied, Cxost'keeping. The only treatment of overabsorbed and underabsorbed overhead that ' ' ' — is conSIStent with the long rmisell-ilag price foundation of the normal ca ' pac1ty concept is the (asiferred charge and deferred credit treatment used 76 under the cycle capacity concept. The Cycle Overhead Concept General In a sense the cycle overhead concept is the normal overhead concept carried to its logical conclusion. The difference between the two is that those favoring the normal overhead concept base their ideas primarily on a long—range average basic price concept, while those favoring the cycle mmncept base their ideas primarily on a cycle concept of inccnne measurement which springs from three factors: 1) a feeling that the business cycle is more appropriate than a year for purposes of income measurement. 2) the sales price ideas inherent in the normal overhead concept. 3) a crude semblance of financial policies attempting to provide for lean years in the years of plenty. 1&11 of these factors are not specifically mentioned by Uuasee advocating the cycle concept, but there is no doubt t 1latall of these factors are at least implicit in most of the dis Cussions . E . arl L1 terature one of the earliest mentions of these ideas occurred in 19 . 01 111 an article by David Cowan. Cowan, after if, "'t—“e—A’fl 77 discussing the then current methods of allocating ”oncost" (the English equivalent of overhead) recommended an hourly allocation basis and further added the cycle concept as follows: If this hour factor correctly represents the variations during a representative cycle of years, in these years of good trade, this account should show a credit balance and in bad years, a debit balance.1 By this he simply meant that his overhead rate would be laased on an average for a cycle of years and that in axjve—average years costs at the estimated hourly rate would be 1J1 excess of actual costs. This excess was due simply to Uua;fact that the cycle scheme would not allow decreasing unit 1:osts, recognizing that the fixed element of overhead “38 SEDread over more units. -In "T“ account form the results would appear as follows: ______________ 123 Wh David Cowan, "With Special Reference to Oncost at 153 should Include: Its Allocations and Recovery," Th2 Wt. XXVII (November 16, 1901), 1251. thdtk) An even earlier reference to the cycle problem is Work" Y George L. Fowler, "Estimating the Cost of Foundry En inéeT\ransactions _c_>_f_ the American Society 9__f_ Mechanical m, Ix (May, 1888 Meeting), 390-397. In this address mflmasi (Des refer to brisk, dull, and fair business but his new-381: is not on the cycle overhead concept, but on the mxmndi 3? for utilizing a different measure of capacity (“fier t;:€! on whether business is brisk, dull or fair in Eit all overhead costs might be assigned to product. 78 Manufacturing Overhead Actual Applied Overhead Costs Overhead (BaSed on Actual Hours Costs multiplied by a cost per hour absorbing the fixed cost element not in terms of actual vol- ume but in terms of average cycle volume). In years of below-average volume the account would shcnv a debit balance due to not recognizing increasing unit costs on the basis of spreading fixed overhead costs over fewer‘units. Cowan actually doesn't follow through on the cycle conceqat, for he suggests that business wouldn't allow a débit laalance in the account to be treated as a deferred (margfi (in effect an asset) in the balance sheet, and there- flue Enach balances would be "cleared off as they arise by Credit (derived-from Profit and Loss."124 In the case of medit loalances (deferred credits) he states that they should be allowed to remain therein as an equaliser of Profits "125 .in,future years of bad trade. \ 124 Cowan, 9p. cit., 1252. Ibid. 79 Cowan's final statements seem to be heavily influenced by the ingrained conversatism characteristic of many accountants. He states, in effect, that debit balances should be treated as losses (reduce income) even though he admits that good theory (in terms of the cycle concept) 'would demand a deferred charge treatment. On the other hand, he Mmmld never consider credit balances as gains (increase iJucome) although he admits their use as an equalizer of pro— fits. In this case Cowan apparently returns to his cycle mmncept, but'at the same time there is an implication of unWilJJngness to face the facts concerning poor years (equalizing profits). Gersham Smith in 1909 brought into the cycle concept the sauna sales price idea which is inherent in normal over— .Tmad, He wrote about a buffer.working into the machine rate ‘3 COVner unforeseen expenses, and also to provide "a reserve innOITnaltimes which could be drawn on in subnormal times, and thus to keep the expense rate fairly even and not to increase it as would otherwise be necessary at a time when Costs can least afford the additional burden."126 In addition to the ion - ' ' g run sales price foundation for overhead \— 126 Gersham Smith, "Distributidn of Indirect Costs by the _ (JunMachlne“H°ur MathOdW . The W Magazine. XXXVII 8‘ 1909), 391. 80 cost absorption, Smith also brings in the idea of providing for the lean years. Smith's idea of providing for lean years out of the profits of good years doesn't seem to make much sense un— less it is considered as a remnant of early thought on financial statement preparation. Early financial statements were prepared only to illustrate dividend—paying ability. The provision for lean years is simply a matter of intro- ducing an income figure averaged for each of the years of the business cycle, so that stockholders would not demand or expect excessive dividends in good years. The extra assets earned in good years, but hidden by the averaging process, are then available for dividends in poor years. The averaging process also provides for those unforseen factors involved in the vicissitudes of everyday business life.127 Gantt in his 1915 address to the American Society of Mechanical Engineers also mentioned the cycle concept, but he immediately expressed his dislike for it. He favored the measurement of idle capacity costs, not the averaging of such czosts over products produced.128 At least two persons \— 127 A 1i Clinton H. Scovell, Cost Accounting and Burden Cation (New York: D. Appleton and Co., 1916), 185-6. 128 C08,: 'H. L. Gantt, "The Relation Between Production and S H ' 9.2. cit., 117. 81 Keppeler Hall, 129 recommended the cycle overhead concept in general terms. in Gantt's audience disagreed with him. One, The other, Ralph Flanders, stated his reasoning in very forceful terms, as follows: We are forced, unfortunately, to reckon with cycles of boom and depression as one of the con- ditions of doing business and this condition is therefore a regular factor in the cost of pro— duction, and should be so treated. . .There is nothing like having all unavoidable expense firmly imbedded in the cost figures, instead of rattling around loose in the ledger.13 In this case Flanders gives the perfect argument for usirng a business cycle as the period over which to measure huxmne, and even though monthly or annual reports are issued he iruiicates that the cycle should be preserved as the basis 0f inuzome measurement via the cycle overhead concept. Per- haPS IPIanders was more specific as a supporter of the cycle cmnceEJt when he stated the difference between his ideas and those §>f Gantt. With respect to this he said: The main difference between the two plans is ‘that with the average rate the burden of carrying -idle equipment and organization through the dull tlimes is distributed into the cost of work in good tiimes, while the proportional rate takes it out of ‘tlle cost system entirely and charges it to profit and loss . l 1 11:29 Ibid., 121 130 Ibid., 123 131 82 To Flanders, Gantt's system is not acceptable, for he (Flanders) considers the cost of idle equipment and organization as unavoidable costs resulting from business cycles which are equally unavoidable. In a sense the position of both men could be reconciled if it were recognized that Flanders was interested in income measure— ment, while Gantt was interested primarily in industrial tranquility gained through identification and elimination of wastes which were not to be included in costs utilized as a foundation for selling prices. In addition, Gantt's measure of idle capacity was based on practical capacity (i.e. . theoretical maximum less unavoidable delays), while Flanders' system produced under- and over—absorbed overhead based on an average or cycle capacity which had absolutely no relation to measures of idle capacity. In fact, the pI‘aCtiCal capacity basis would rarely, if ever, produce an over-absorbed burden, if handled properly.132 My Obj ectors Tqiere were some early objectors to the cycle overhead COn Cgpt - Among them was William E. McHenry, who subscribed l\“__~‘§“_____; 132 See Footnote 146. 83 to the Gantt position, and stated with reference to a comparison of the two ideas that the proportional plan of including in production costs only that portion of overhead costs actually used had been before the public for several years: Yet it seems to be so little understood that I have heard practical men, as well as professional accountants, advocate a system whereby certain percentages, determined from averages of several years, are used, so that under full running con— ditions a credit is established in the expense fund upon which lean years may draw without increasing the cost. And they also contend that this is substantially the same as the principle for which we are fighting!!! The principle in McHenry's mind was that waste should be recognized as waste and "that IT cosrs SOMETHING TO DO NOTHING."134 The editor of The Accountant also objected to the cynsle concept but for a different reason. He wrote, It should be borne in mind that the goal to be aimed at is not to level out all the results of a ,year or a series of years, so as to make them as ianiform as possible, but to bring prominently before ‘the notice of those responsible the actual facts, by 110 means the least important of which would be that VVith a full factory the cost of production is far 14283 than when the factory is half empty. This, how— eVer, is a point which of necessity is glossed over 145 the standing expenses are to be averaged over the ‘\_'__ 133 McHenry, op. cit., 686. 1:3 4mm” 678. 84 output of a comparatively long period.135 In this case the editor was certainly not in favor (pf the cycle concept, but he was not yet considering the cxancept of idle capacity except in the broad sense of iJicreases and decreases in product costs depending on volume 'variations. His comments came before the many criticisms of Cflhirch's supplementary rate. Contemporary Literature Among the earliest of the contemporary writers who might.be considered is G. Charter Harrison. He presented a 136 very cmmcise but at the same time confused point of view mxmxarning the cycle concept. He spoke first of segregating theicost of idleness from cost of production for purposes of meMMJring efficiency; He quantifies the cost of idleness bYtRflseasona1 and cyclical causes. He added, in a comment whicfli actually covered the normal and cycle capacity concepts, that "this new idea carried the definite implication that acuual costs were not real, that the true cost of the product involved overhead at normal capacity."145 Eflflsryg As in the case of the normal capacity concept, the __~‘_§_________ 143 Ibid., 9. 144 . .. - - - - C Joseph A. Mauriello, Convertibility of Direct and onwartional Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin,xxxv, Sec. l.(March, 145 N. . —JL21§. Bulletin, XXVIII, Sec. 1.(Ju1y 15, 1947), 1388. Theodore Lang, "Concepts of Cost, Past and Present," -.‘. if“. 89 cycle overhead concept involves a decidedly different point of view from that employed in the supplementary rate. The supplementary rate, even with the modifications of Gantt and Whitmore, was intended to focus attention on waste or inefficiency. This is not true of the cycle capacity con- cept. The cycle capacity concept has wrapped up in it the sales price ideology‘of the normal capacity concept as well as some crude semblance of dividend policy related to averaging income over the cycle in such a way that the extra profits of good yearslwill be hidden and held over for the lean years. In addition to these ideas, however, the primary motive of the cycle concept must be considered—~that is, the idea that the business cycle. is more appropriate than a year for purposes of income measurement. Even though monthly, quarterly, or annual statements are prepared, the cycle con— cept would be preserved via the absorption or averaging of fixed costs over the Cycle. The difference between capacity utilized and maximum caPaCity with or without allowance for unavoidable delay does result in-a fair measure of idle capacity costs or waste, b“ the difference between capacity utilized and a cyclical normal" capacity represents something entirely different. 90 In fact, under the cycle capacity concept there can be no idle capacity; in the sense of a loss, in that fluctuations in volume are expected or unavoidable. Underabsorbed fixed overhead represents a deferred charge or cost applicable to the future while underabsorbed fixed overhead represents a deferred credit or provision for future costs. The Practical Capacity Concept General Allocating overhead to product on the basis of practical capacity is actually the logical outgrowth of the "supplementary rate". In this case a true measure of un- utilized capacity is determined, for practical capacity represents maximum attainable output in strict physical terms Without the recognition of the sales factor which is found in the normal or the cycle capacity concept. The difference between maximum attainable output and aCtHall output pinpoints the costs of unutilized capacity. The a'Ctual dollar amount of unutilized capacity costs is dete‘l‘fmzlned by taking the ratio of utilized to practical Capacity and applying it to fixed costs. An approximation of this calculation is made when fixed and variable costs are included in one overhead rate based on practical capacity. 91 If it is assumed that variable costs are directly variable Vvith output there should be no quantitative difference between the amounts determined by both methods. An important consideration in the case of practical capacity is that it would not allow the possibility of a ' 146 credit volume variance. . This is true, since practical capacity is maximum attainable capacity in a strict physical sense, and a credit volume variance demands in the case of practical. capacity a volume higher than maximum attainable capacity--an impossible situation. The credit volume variance is a necessary part of normal or cycle overhead or any over— head measurement base which is less than practical capacity. Chu rch, WhitmoreL and Gantt and Practical Capacity Church, as previously mentioned, worked with the idea 0f maximum capacity under the most favorable circumstances.147 It Could be insisted that Church's mention of the most \ 146 the One exception to this would be a situation wherein o uhavoidable delay computation included in the determination an Practical capacity was in excess of the amount needed in tey Period for such things as employees personal time, main- nance and other expected downtime. 147 Church, The Proper Distribution 9; Expense Burden, 9321;” 85. 92 .favorable circumstances is the same thing as the unavoidable (ielay allowed for in practical capacity. On the other hand 'unost favorable conditions" could be taken to mean an "ideal" (:apacity which did not allow for unavoidable delays. It (does seem, though, that Church was really in favor of practical capacity. Whitmore, however, was clearly in favor of practical capacity, for he wrote of full capacity under normal work cxnuditions with allowances for unavoidable lost time.148 Gantlzalso seemed to favor practical capacity, for there is m: other reasonable interpretation of his usual comments about the factory running at full or normal capacity and the . _ 149 waste due to idle facilities. 993%: writers and Practitioners and Practice Capacity At the 1924 National Association of Cost Accountants A“mail-Meeting in a discussion concerning debatable points in<3k5t accounting there were some who spoke in favor of praCtiCLal capacity and stated that commercial conditions \— 148 Whitmore, "Factory Accounting As Applied to Machine 22. cit., 439. 149 . . Gantt, "The Relation Between Production and Costs,” QE-Clt, 117. I“. ' Shops ' II 93 . . . 150 should never affect capac1ty determination. At the same meeting Howard Knapp, when speaking in favor of practical capacity, said that expected output is not to be considered . . . . 151 in determining capac1ty, and then added: When burden rates are planned on the basis of probably business obtainable, the accounting does not determine the cost of unused space and equipment, a mostlggportant item in any state- ment of earnings. Knapp's comments point out that only practical capacity measures the cost of unutilized facilities. This _ .- . . 153 mmne pOint is made quite clear by Frank B. Wolfe in 1927. After 1927 practical capacity doesn't seem to have been considered too much in cost accounting literature. This is Pethaps due to the fact that the greatest business depression hlliistory came upon the scene and gave great impetus to the nonmal overhead concept, which seems to have become the Discussion, "Some Debatable Points in Cost Accountzing Theory," National Association 9; Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1924, 266-9. 151 St C. Howard Knapp, "Variation From Predetermined Asandérds of Burden in Manufacturing Costs," National tJflfifiéiigygg.é§ Cost Accountants'Yearbook, 1924, 210. 152 Ibid., 217. duct Frank 8' Wolfe, "Providing a Check on Unused Pro- Ind ion capacity; Accounting for the Cost of Idle Plant," M Management, LXXIV (November, 1927), 305-9, 94 predominant form of capacity measure utilized for allocating overhead costs. _§ome Special Problems: Categories of Machines or Capacity Church and Whitmore, in addition to working with practical capacity, also considered machines purchased for occasional or special use. Church's relevant comments were as follows: The idleness of a machine may or may not be considered as the fault of that machine, if, for instance, a machine was found to be idle nineteen- twentieths of its time, this might be due to one of two causes. Either the process was rare but essential or the machine itself was largely super— fluous. He stated further that in the first case the special mmfliine purchased for occasional but essential use should hams a charge for use that is quite high since all the charges for its upkeep and presence were incurred solely fortflne sake of the occasional use. In other words, expected usage Exrovided the means of allocating such costs to pro— mxmiori. In the second case he believed that the retention Oftme Inachine was primarily a matter of accommodation (peak loads), .in which case the shop as a whole should bear the burden and not the unlucky piece of work that happened to be \ Church, The Proper Distribution pf Expense Burden, \‘I 55. «+143? 95 put on the machine at any time. In other words, Church felt that these idle time costs were unavoidable and therefore applicable to the whole shop for whose benefit the machines 155 were kept in the first place. A slight modification in reasoning would have made Church's position much more tenable. The necessary change is that the products or specific processes for which the second category of machines was kept as an accommodation should be charged with the idle time, not the shop as a Whole. Whitmore, when he considered specific items of equip— ment, divided machines into three classes, viz., [H machines of full efficiency, whose use is general and whose full capacity should under proper conditions be constantly used. [2 machines of full efficiency, installed for special and occasional use, and not upon a calculation of continuous operation. Bjmachines which are not of the highest efficiency, ‘but which are maintained and used when other machines which could do the work more economically are busy. 56 \ 155 Ibid. #156 Malr Whitmore, "Factory Accounting As Applied to C me Shops," 92. cit., 438. 96 For the first class of machines Whitmore recommended a practical capacity basis, for the second class he re— commended expected use, and for the third class he also recommended practical capacity, for he said, their use is certainly worth no more than the hourly rate so determined, and probably even on this basis the work is expensively done [for the reason that these are not the most efficient machines]; and 2nd, the actual cost of keeping such machines in the shop cannot be too plainly shown.157 In effect Church and Whitmore agreed on the capacity loasis appropriate to each of the three classes. The only clifference lay in their original controversy as to whether ‘thea idle capacity of group three should or should not become a Ewart of product cost. Church's reasoning for allocating the .idle time costs to product does not seem to be his usueil sales price idea and appears much superior to Whitmore's reasuoning. Accurate cost keeping seems to be the basis of ChUITfli's reasoning, in the sense that machines kept for purpCMses of accommodating peak loads or breakdowns of other ‘ -nmchiaies are absolutely necessary, and represent unavoidable Costs cu'a form of insurance which could hardly be categorized as WaSte. Both of these men had one critic, Andrew Murdoch. 97 Murdoch believed the classifications put forth would involve a hair-splitting procedure which ”would destroy much of the usefulness of the records of idle machines for purposes of comparison."158 He believed the only way to get an accurate figure for idle capacity costs was to use a practical capacity figure for all facilities. In a strict sense Murdoch ‘Mas correct. However, he was not considering, as were Church .and.Whitmore, the special nature of the machine purchased for mments of Church and Whitmore on categories of machines. They are 1) Capacity consists of machinery and other facilities; or,all fixed costs are related to long—lived asset acquisitions.159 \— 158 Co Andrew A. Murdoch, "The PrOper Treatment of Machine StsACriticism and a Theory,” The Journal 9; Accountancy, In (December, 1906), 127. 159 This also seems to be assumed in the normal and c ycle standard, in prices of services (power, light, etc.), in c;uantity of services consumed and variations in overhead (Expenses other than services. Furthermore, he considered algl of these costs as they were divisible into variable costs, fitxed monthly charges (salaries), fixed charges per working (hay'(timekeeper paid on hourly basis) and fixed charges for dajf‘worked (men paid hourly who worked only when their depnartment worked).181 All of these variations were utilized in <3rder that Mr. Harrison could answer in detail the inevi— tabfile "why" concerning the difference between actual and Standard costs . Apparently Mr. Harrison's ideas on showing these variertions fell on deaf ears, for no one else seemed to 182 ‘ adOpt liis variations. Through the twenties, overhead \ 180 P G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting To Aid roductxion," Industrial Management, LVI (November, 1918), 397. 181 G. Charter Harrison, "Scientific Basis for Cost 'ACCOunthIglu Industrial Management, LIX (March, 1920). 239-41- I182 Mr. Harrison included these same ideas in his 1930 teXt. s . Ybrk.‘“£££§9§£§.§2§£§ Fabllshed by Ronald Press Company of New 121 variances (other than over—or underabsorbed) were largely . , 183 ignored by textbook writers and the literature. The standard cost idea for overhead accounting made little head- way. Lawrence (1925), Schlatter (1927), Amidon and Lang (1928), Sanders (1929) did not consider Harrison's idea at all, and did nothing concerning overhead variances except perhaps to compare total overhead costs with standard over- head costs and produce the already familiar over-and under— absorbed overhead . 184 At the 1931 National Association of Cost Accountants meeting Charles Reitell advocated two overhead variance Classifications. These were a volume and a controllable Variance. ‘ The volume variance was computed by deducting bUdgeted costs for actual volume from budgeted costs for Standard volume (expected long—range average). This variance, “x ‘ 183 An exception to this would be the excellent dis— CuSalon on standard costs at the 1926 National Association of Cost Accountants Meeting. See National Association 9_f_ Cost WE'Yearbook 1926, 97-194. 184 W. B. Lawrence, Cost Accounting (New York: Prentice- Halll Inc., 1925). ( Charles E‘. Schlatter, Elementag Cost Accounting, Siew YOI‘k: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1927) (no mention of andards at all). of Cost L. Cleveland Amidon and Theodore Lang, Essentials -.- ~-~ Accounting (New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1928), 273. MCGraw_H. Thomas Henry Sanders, Industrial Accounting (New York: 111 Book Co., Inc., 1929), 277. 122 then, was nothing more than unutilized fixed costs or over- Litilized fixed costs (in the case where actual volume exceeded sytandard volume). The controllable variance was determined byr deducting actual cost from budgeted costs for actual vrilume. The controllable variance, although it was intended tc> indicate efficiency of controlling variable costs by pro- ducfl:ion men, did not do so, since it included with costs of tecflinical inefficiency, variations in the prices of variable as vvell as fixed overhead costs. 85 In 1932 Eric Camman published his ideas in book form and aseparated overhead variations into variations related to Guantrollable expense and fixed charges.186 Camman's two variiinces, in effect, yielded a fixed charge variation which was 'tlie same as idle capacity costs and the controllable EXPenisse variation which was intended to measure the effective- neSS c>f using variable overhead costs. The major problem with (Zamman's ideas was that they were based on basic or "bogexz" standards which were to be retained as yardstiCks \ 185 Reitell, gp. cit., 24—30. E 186Camman had used this same breakdown in 1926. See Ogic A“ Camman,"Uses 9f Standard Costs,"National Association - 9% Agcountants'Yearbook 1926, 125 and 131. 123 as long as techniques were stable, and WhiCh were not to be: Changed to reflect changes in price levels. Price—level cflianges were to be worked into the analysis via index number achustments, and both actual and standard costs were to be caixried in the accounts. Camman's analysis, then, of necxassity had to be considered in terms of overall percentage cheuiges for the many elements making up overhead costs. This in eaffect produced a highly complex mathematical analysis whicfli did yield the above variances, but in such a way as to make; cone wonder as to the efficacy of the results.187 Soon after this the now familiar three—variance technique (volume, efficiency and price) appeared, even thoufgflinany of the writers then, as today, disagreed on the exact: Iiature of the three variances.188 All in all, when it came ‘tt: standard overhead costing, the idea was primarily a matteI? of segregating the differences between actual and Standatrd.costs- In some instances, that is, in the case of ( 187 Eric A. Camman, Basic Standard Costs (New York: The Amarican institute Publishing Co., Inc., 1932), 69-81. 188 Acco . Compare: Charles F. Schlatter, Advanced Cost --Efl$fiL g (New York: John Wiley and Sons., Inc., 1939), 122-4. YbrkyM_ John G. Blocker, Essentials 9f Cost Accounting (New ° C3Graw—Hill Book Co., 1942), 323. ' Adolf Matz, Othel J. Curry and George W. Frank, SSBDunting (Cincinatti, Ohio: Southwestern Publishing ' 1957), 576-582. SOSt A. Co. " 124 fixed overhead costs, the variances were primarily a matter of differences between standard and actual volume (volume variance). This holds whether one summarizes all fixed costs in one category or follows Harrison's ideas on different categories of fixed costs, variations in working days per month, and pure and simple idle capacity. With variable overhead costs the differences between actual and standard costs represented the costs of technical inefficiency as well as price differences which could or Could not be considered justified and therefore efficient or ine£ficient. In some instances, although not all, the price and physical usage (efficiency) variances were separated.189 The improvement of standard costing over actual costing actually involved nothing more than the ability to identify wastes more precisely. In actual costing there was no real Standard of comparison, and therefore the measure of waste was Simply a matter of comparing figures for different periods to cIheck the direction of efficiency. In standard costing there was an attempt to segregate and show explicitly the Costs Of inefficiency. The greatest problem with standard costing, as 189 Schlatter, Advanced _C_ost Accounting, op. cit., 125 presented, was that even though waste was identified, it was only in a broad or overall sense. Before remedial measures could be taken, intensive analysis was necessary in order to determine the more exact nature or causes of inefficiency, as well as efficiency which could have been averaged out of sight. This type of analysis was also necessary with actual costs, so that the real difference between the two systems was in introducing a yardstick. One could easily say, then, that the standard cost system identified categories of wastes, but after the identification a great deal still had to be done in order to prevent continuation of the wastes. The ResponsibilitygIdea At practically the same time that standard costing was developing in the above sense, it was also developing in the sense of tying cost incurrence to the responsibility for COst incurrence. This is the idea B. A. Franklin ex— preSSed when he wrote in 1912 The expense of the department is totaled first to a "controllable expense", this being the amount Occurrable in the department, and so under the con— trol and supervision of the foreman. Franklin's analysis was excellent up to the point \\ 190 Franklin, pp. 233., 428. 126 where he spoke of relating labor dollars or hours to pppal departmental expense rather than to controllable expense, in order to see that "the executive has an Opportunity to study "191 expense, to experiment with it, and to control it. He lost sight of the effects of volume and of uncontrollable expenses in the resulting ratios. The same importance of cost responsibility also was expressed by Harrison a few years later, but only in a gen— . . . . 92 eral sense Without explanatory or descriptive material. Jordon and Harris utilized the same concept in illustrative departmental burden statements, but when they calculated Comparative percentages they did so on the basis of total 193 cost, as did Franklin. These men had the right idea, but it was not effectively carried out or fulfilled until it was attached to the idea of budgetary control, especially through use Of the flexible budget. Reitell stated this very nicely in 1931 \Vhen he wrote, \ 191 Ibid., 429. 192 G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting in the New Industrial Day," pp. cit., 443. 3 Jordon and Harris, pp. cit., 295. 127 Our expense classification or Operating code, as we call it, must be changed so that it will fit exactly into the definite organization set-up. It will then be possible to charge each and every supervisor from foreman to president with items of expense that are wholly, completely and entirely under his or her control. Each in turn will be held strictly responsible for these expenses which are his. And each will be placed under-budgetarygpontrol to see that responsibility is maintained. In addition, Reitell did not consider the controllable ovexrhead variance as only a lump—sum figure, for he worked Witfli individual items of overhead, the person responsible, thE! causes of difference, the remedy and a report of progress in 195 . . . ea follow—up sheet. Finally Reitell described how imFHDrtant his plan was for overhead costs: The importance of this plan of determining controllable variance must be driven home hard. The identification of controllable variances in the plant with supervisory responsibility con- stitutes a tremendous stride forward in redeeming overhead expenses from the class of illusive un— certainties to placing them under a rigid and definite control. Budgeting was absolutely necessary in order to help pinpoint responsibility, while flexible budgeting was ab- solLrtialy necessary in order to allow for the difference 1r‘p§~*~_____— 194 , . Reitell, pp. p;p., 17. 195_Ibid., 29-32. 196 128 between planned and actual volume. glassy The rise of increased accumulations of capital and ccxnpetitive conditions around the turn of the nineteenth cenitury brought forth the increasing importance of over— head costs and the necessity for waste elimination. Out of ttuase conditions came the recognition of idle facilities, the: cost of which had to be removed from other production COStns in order to yield cost figures that could be compared t0 Cietermine the comparative extent and direction of efficiency. Attempts to measure idle facilities gave rise to a formn of standardization for overhead costs which blossomed intxa standardization for all costs of production so that 'Wastaes or inefficiencies could be isolated. In the case of OVeIfliead costs this meant ultimately a breakdown of the diffFearence between standard and actual overhead costs into the Inany categories demanded by G. Charter Harrison or into the licwvnmme usual volume, price, and efficiency categories. IntE31531ve analysis of these variances with action based thereupon was usually considered the means of eliminating the <2Ontinuance of the wastes identified. Paralleling the rise of standard costs and the analysis 129 of variances, the ideas of accumulating costs by respon— sibilities developed into its completed state in the form of flexible budgeting. Overhead costing today still emphasizes variance analysis and the responsibility accumulations of flexible budgets as the basis of overhead cost control.197 Income Measurement and the Development of Overhead Costing series; Thus far in this functional approach to the history 0f overhead costing, sales price determination and efficiency measures have been discussed as the primary motives, his- torically speaking, behind cost accounting in general and Overhead costing in particular. With this in mind, it is not difficult to believe that cost accounting for income measurement accepted with little, if any, qualification the figure calculated for other cost finding purposes. Early Wriplggs Garcke and Fells (1887) certainly recognized in a v , - . . . . ery luCid manner the relationship between inventory valuation \‘ 197 RObert N. Anthony, Management Accounting (Homewood, IlllrlOis: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956), 268-324. StUGi R. L. Brummet, Overhead Costing, Michigan Business Michies’ Vol. XIII, No. 2 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: UniverSity of (Jan, 1957), 139-51. 130 198 and income measurement, but the nature of the cost com- ponents they used for inventory purposes make one wonder xvhat the true rationale behind their cost calculations was. For example they wrote: When the indirect charges and depreciation are of a more or less fixed character, it is probably sufficient to know the cost of 189 article in wages and materials only. . This comment was clarified a little later when they unare speaking of establishment charges (selling costs): The principals of a business can always judge what percentage of gross profit upon cost is neceSsary to cover fixed establishment charges and interest on capital. A few years later Garcke and Fells further clarified thstir comment when in the 7th edition (1922) of their text theyr admitted that their primary interest was a cost for PriCKa determination. At this time Garcke and Fells were defETHSing their exclusion of fixed establishment charges and iJiterest on capital from costs of production. Their reaSOHing was that these costs were costs of production in a ’ . . wldEfi sense, but were not costs of production insofar as \——— 198 Garcke and Fells, pp. cit., 122-3. 199 Ibid., 6. .200 Ibid., 73. 131 cost of production regulates price. Garcke and Fells were essentially interested in a variable cost or out-of—pocket cost concept for pricing purposes. When allocating manu- facturing overhead to products produced they were assuming tfliat such costs were variable in nature. Similar comments are applicable in the case of G. P. Kharton who wrote an entire book, Textile Manufacturers' Enookkeeping (1889), and then, when speaking of inventory \naluation, advocated using net selling price. 02 What then “mas his intention in accumulating cost figures? Could it be: anything other than the then usual sales price and efficiency measures? The same is true of J. S. Lewis, who said in the case Of eastablishment charges (selling expenses) that it mattered littile if all were charged to profit and loss or allocated to PIRDduct, "for the mere purposes of commercial book— keepiaig."203 He then emphasized allocating establishing chargens to products for purposes of estimating, and a Separfrtion between factory and selling expenses for purposes ‘-~——1__~__________ 201 Ibid., (Seventh edition, 1922). Footnote on page 119. .202 Norton, pp. cit., 259-60. See also Footnotes 32, 33, supra. 1203 Lewis, pp. cit., 174. and 34’ 132 of measuring manufacturing and commercial efficiency better.204 Later writers were much clearer as to the basic .foundations of their cost figures, for they readily admitted ‘that the major or only purposes of costing were to help set asedling prices, to measure efficiency and to control costs. Punong these writers were Church, Hatfield, Franklin, Jordon auid Harris, Hattersley, and Paton and Stevenson.205 Breakdown of Commercial and Manufacturipg Overhead As pOinted out preViously, most of the early writers anti practitioners of costing did not separate selling and marnifacturing overhead. As time progressed the separation diti take place, but the basis for separation was not income measnlrement. Objectives of the separation were the more aCCLurate cost buildup to selling prices and the separation 0f Ccnnmercial and manufacturing efficiency. A more 204 Ibid., 174—9. 2oschurch, The Proper Distribution Q§_E§E§£§§.BH£Q§34 Hatfield, pp. p;£., 293-5. Franklin, pp. plp., 421. Jordan and Harris, pp. pip., 428. LXIV G. Stanley Hattersley, "Costing", The Accountant, (May 28, 1921), 681. 0f.Ac William A. Paton and Russell A. Stevenson, Principles ‘T'tegsflggpipg (New York: The MacMillan Co., 1922), 614. .20 6See the Section "Influence of Price Determination on 133 sophisticated approach to this separation which seemed related to income measurement was present in comments such as those made by the editor of The Accountant, who advocated 'that inventoriable costs should stop at the point where the 207 :responsibility of the works manager ceased. The same cnamment was also made by Frederick A. Halsey, who in so cicung exhibited a very impressive knowledge of the relation— 208 sllip between inventory valuation and income measurement. ' The said concerning the procedure of including selling expenses irl inventory, . . .it inventories the expenses and makes them show as an asset, a condition of things that cannot be deferred.209 This all sounds very well until one considers that eveni though selling costs are not production costs in the sensua of being incurred by and for the factory, they can be COnSidered inventoriable as assets. The idea that such costs are rust subject to the control of the factory superintendent _1_______7 . the Content of Overhead" pp. 18-43. 207 Editorial, "Cost Accounts," The Accountant, XXXII (June 17, 1905), 728. 208 . , , Norris, pp. c1t., 397—400. 209 Ibid., 398. 134 sounds more like J. S. Lewis' idea of separating manufacturing and commercial efficiency210 than income measurement. If elimination of selling costs from inventories is to be considered as an income measurement concept, it must be considered crude at best, for there is good reason under many conditions to inventory selling costs if one follows the usual matching concept of accounting. Under this con- cept costs are associated with the income they produce, so that if at the end of the year there are some costs, selling or otherwise, applicable to future sales, they must be treated as deferred charges, which is in effect the same thing as an inventory item or an asset in the year-end balance sheet. Inclusion of selling costs in inventory is a point Vi‘EJOrously stressed by William B. Castenholz at the 1922 National Association of Cost Accountants annual meeting,211 212 and by J. S. Seidman in 1946. Both of these men were fimly and justifiably convinced that attitudes like those \‘7 210 Lewis, pp. cit., 179. and A. 711William B. Castenholz, "The Application of Selling of Co Ihinistrative Expenses to Product," National Association ‘~-~§J; Accountants'Yearbook,l922, 127-154. 212 in Inxr J. S. Seidman, "Do We Mistreat Administrative Expenses 286~8 ‘entory," The Journal pf Accountancy, LXXXI (April, 1946), ‘ I—E— 135 213 of Halsey and the editor of The Accountant were quite shallow for income measurement purposes. Exclusion of Imputed Interest from Manufacturing Overhead In the early history of cost accounting imputed interest was considered to be an element of manufacturing <:ost. Most of the arguments for its inclusion have been very riicely summarized by Clinton H. Scovell, probably the most aactive of those advocating the inclusion of interest as a cxast. In one of his early works Scovell listed among the ibenuefits of including interest in costs such things as more acncurate price determination, determining efficiency of vadiious items of equipment and determination of the cost of , . . 214 ca rrying inventory . A few years later Scovell stated that unless interest is iJicluded as a cost it would be impossible to 1. compare efficiency of alternative methods. 2. allow for the time element in costs. 3. distinguish profit on two or more kinds of business by the same management. 4. measure cost of carrying inventory. 5. compare costs and profits of companies which differ as to the number of component parts they make or buy. “K‘— 213 Footnotes 207 and 209 Supra. 214 Appl' Clinton H- SCOVEll, Cost Accounting and Burden “‘~<£SEEE$gg_(New York: D. Appleton and Co., 1916), 97—104. 136 6. compare costs in owned or rented plants. 7. compare costs of purchased or privately generated current. 8. eliminate the effect of varieties of financing on costs. 215 9. make uniform cost plans for associations. For the most part Scovell concentrated on price determination, comparison of alternatives, and equalization of such things as methods of financing and differences in cxast of facilities. Inventory valuation and income measure— Hmndt as such did not seem to be very important in his del iberations . The ultimate exclusion of imputed interest from marnafacturing costs seems primarily related to income measurement. For example, Jordon and Harris, in their Sununary of arguments against the inclusion of interest in C0512, included the following six items among twelve arguments, [1] Interest does not represent values received or parted with. [23 Inclusion of interest in cost leads to inflation of inventories. [3] Inclusion of interest leads to anticipation of profits. [EEIInterest inclusion might result in showing a profit on the books even though no goods have been sold. [53.8ankers shave down inventories by the amount of interest included. 1r_p“~‘___-_~_ 215 ’ Clinton H. Scovell, December 27, 1918 address to the (takgmfiuarican Association of University Instructors in Accounting ‘arl from Jordon and Harris, pp. cit., 431. 137 Kg Interest in sion produces misleading financial clu statements.216 In addition, Jordon and Harris mention that interest can be shown in statistical statements and kept out of the 217 , . . . books. This in effect yielded practically all the benefits mentioned by Scovell, but left for emphasis the income measurement approach.' These comments by Jordon and Harris are in perfect agreement with those of a special I commuttee of the American Institute of Accountants (1918). This committee also mentioned the possibility of side calxculations to yield the benefits desired by Scovell, but tduay'emphasized with regard to income measurement: Interest on investment is not an expenditure, but is at best only an anticipation of profits and, as such, has no logical standing in the compu— tation of production costs. J. M. Clark, the eminent economist, made some interesting comments on the inclusion of imputed interest in nuanufacturing costs. He said that books which included \ 216 Jordon and Harris, pp. cit., 443. 217 Ibid. Rel . 218"Report of the Special Committee on Interest in atllln to Cost," The American Institute pf Cost Accountants' 1 __9_1§ Xearbook, 110 . 13E interest as a cost were not prepared for the purposes of financial accounting (construction of a balance sheet and income account). Such books were prepared primarily for such books interest 219 various types of cost analysis, and on must be deducted before making up the income account. Clark clarified his comments when he spoke of in— ventory valuation and suggested that inventory valuation Should result in showing income available for dividends and interest to just the extent that goods have been sold for rmare than they cost. 'Inventory valuations should be based CH1 the actual value of manufactured goods, not the value 220 that they "ought to have." Perhaps more than anything else, the controversy over "intnarest as a cost" shows the rising influence of income detEBrmination on cost accounting. The reduction of this Comtxroversy to the ideas eXpressed by Jordon and Harris, the Amexrican Institute of Accountants committee, and Clark, is is irrterestingly paralleled in time with the emergence of. Such IDrilliant financial accounting theorists as Hatfield and FNaton. The rise of financial accounting theorists might ~1.“__~_______ 219 Clark, 92. cit., 255-6. 229Ibid., 239—40. 139 explain the more definite consideration of income measure- ment as an aspect of cost accounting in the period surrounding World War I. The SupplementaryiRate and Its Sequel The supplementary rate of Church‘wasan outgrowth of attempts to measure efficiency, detect waste, and determine price. Its subsequent develOpment by Whitmore, Gantt, et. al., Changed the quantitative aspects but still retained the basic yfioundations of Church. Nevertheless, there were those who dixi an impressive job of adapting the idle capacity concept tC> the twin problems of inventory valuation and income 21 measurement . Further development of the basic concept into the nornual overhead idea was based solely on the depression pSYCfliology of a long—range average basic selling price. A trarHaition to the cycle overhead idea is apparently based on El cyclical income concept, but in conjunction with the Cyclfi concept there is too much implied unvdllingness to face 1ihe facts of poor years and willingness to hide the facts lications it has for overhead costing are contained in later sections of this chapter and in Chapter Five. We must thfan be content for the moment with the assertion (to be juStified later) that the literature of economics has an X 2 s For an excellent discussion of these points of view Ge : of Lawrence R. Chenault, ”Business Behavior and the Theory tile Firm," The Accounting Review, XXIX (October 1954L Ac James S. Barley, "Recent Developments in Cost PO:§“lnting and the Marginal Analysis,” Tpp Journpl pf editicgi Economy, LXIII (June, 1955), 227—42. \ 153 important bearing on the accounting problems of income measurement and overhead costing. Cost control poses no apparent problem to orthodox economic theory. The many real problems inherent in cost control or making costs conform to standards of efficiency are for the most part assumed out of existence by the con— dept of the economic man. This economic man, being thoroughly rational, tends automatically toward profits maximization, therefore, there is no necessity to consider cost control, for the economic man will determine the least—cost method of manufacture and will automatically make sure that actual results conform to the minimum expenditure of inputs. The View that cost control is not part of traditional economic theory was in effect supported by Joel Dean when he said that the least—cost combination of inputs "is not always known, not always politic, and sometimes not even sought,” as is traditionally assumed.3 Dean added that the maximization of EProfits in the short—run "is seldom the dominant objective, aUdthe pressure for efficiency is not, as assumed in the theory, constant and always sufficient." 3 Joel Dean, Managerial Economics (New York: Prentice Hall Inc., 1951) 252-3. 4 Ibid., 257. 154 For purposes of cost control and waste elimination Dean relies on the traditional variance analysis of cost accounting which he complements with the use of correlation analysis techniques. In either case the approach is still the same, that is, one accumulates the variances and then analyzes them to find root causes which are to be eliminated? Since this dissertation relates to problems of cost accounting, it is the matter of cost and volume variations within the confines of the economist's short period that is of major significance. For all practical purposes the matter of revenue will be ignored or, when it is necessary to discuss revenue, it will be assumed to conform to the usual presentation in non—perfect competition. Cost from the viewpoint of economics will be conSidered in terms of the usual dichotomy, that is, variable and fixed costs. Variable Costs and Volume Variation general From the viewpoint of economic marginalism the only COSts which are of significance are the costs which vary 5 Ibid. Footnote on page 253 and Joel Dean, "Correlation Analysis of Cost Variation," The Accounting Review, XII (March,l937): 55—60. 155 with volume. These are the variable costs which are usually assumed to vary with output in the form approximated by a U—shaped curve.6 The U-shaped unit cost curve is accepted because the variable inputs are considered to be combined with a fixed amount of fixed inputs. If there is an Optimum manner of utilizing a fixed input with variable inputs, as there should be, utilization above and below optimum will result in diminishing returns, which is the same as in~ creasing costs. An optimum with increaSing costs above and below optimum yields the familiar U—shaped unit cost curves , for variable and marginal costs. Not too many years ago economists began to have some success in quantifying some of their analytical framework,7 and also began to question the assumption of fixed inputs.8 Such work brought forth a number of statistical cost studies as well as a great deal of controversy concerning the utility of marginalism. These studies and their related controversies In the above comments a U-shaped curve is spoken of Only with reference to variable and marginal costs per unit. Total costs per unit will also vary with output in the form approximated by a U—shaped curve. _ One of the first cost studies was Joel Dean's, §fiatistical Determination of Costs With §pegi§l Reference to Marginal Costs, Studies in Business Administration, Vol. VII. NO. 1 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1936L l45pp, 8George Stigler, "Production and Distribution in the Short Run," The Journal of Political Economy, XLVII (June,l939h 305-27. _— 156 have led to a reconsideration of the usually assumed relationships of marginal and variable costs to output. Statistical Cost Studies Most of those actually making statistical cost studies have come to the conclusion that the marginal cost curve, and therefore the related variable cost curve, were . . . , 9 . both flat Within the confines of actual Operations. This conclusion did not invalidate the assumption of U-shaped curves as such, but it did extend the center portion of the U to such a degree as to relegate the increasing and de— creasing portions of the curves to the oblivion of insignifi- cance. Of course, not all agreed with the conclusions of these studies. One appraiser expressed his concluSions as follows: The literature on statistical cost functions so far produced has certainly, as all measurements are bound to do, enhanced understanding and aware— ness of the complexity of the subject, but I cannot help thinking that it also represents a case which 9 Theodore Yntema (chairman), "Round Table on Cost FUnctions and Their Relation to Imperfect Competition," Papers and Proceedings of the Fifty—second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, December 1929, The American Economic Review, XXX, part 2 (March, 1940). 400-402. 157 bears out just that and not much else.lo Most of the objectors point to what they call built~in linear biases and the fact that slight deviations in linearity could yield the usual cost curvature or approximations to it.ll When one considers variability in the fixed factors of production which coincides withthe insiStent demands for flexibility in industrial capacity, there seems to be little alternative to accepting the conclusions of most of these cost studies. The connection between the statistical cost studies, variability of fixed factors, and flexibility is inherent in Mr. Dean's studies. He purposely sought out plants Which had experienced wide fluctuations in output; that is, whether he realized it or not he sought out plants which would of necessity be built with maximum flexibility. Flexibility would be a matter of utilizing as little fixed Plant as possible and/or using many small machines rather than larger machines. Flexibility either reduces the Significance of fixed factors or increases their variability, lO Hans Staehle, "The Measurement of Statistical Cost FUnctions: An Appraisal of Recent Contributions," The flflggican Economic Review, XXXII (June,l942),333. llggig. and Caleb Smith, "The Cost-Output Relation fOr the U. 8. Steel Corporation,” The Review gf Economic Statistics, XXIV (November,l942),166—76. M 158 which gives us fewer than the usual reasons for accepting a U-shaped cost curve, especially within the normal Operating limits. Controversy over Marginalism The controversy over marginalism involves essentially the applicability of marginalism for short-period price and output determination. At times the argument has raged about the calculability Of revenue curves and at other times about the calculability of cost curves Of their applicability, even if they could be calculated. One Of the most persistent critics Of marginalism, Professor Eiteman, has shaped his attack from both the revenue and cost sides. When revenue curves are the focal point Of his attack, the matter Of calculability is para— mount. In fact, in one Of his most extensive works he basés his whole argument against marginalism on the inability to <3etermine revenue curves having any real significance. In 13 Other works the focal point is cost. His arguments run Wilford J. Eiteman, Price Determination—Business Eggctice Versus Economic Theory, Bureau of Business Research, Report NO. 16 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan, 1949),39 pp 13Wilford J. Eiteman, "Factors Determining the Location Of'the Least Cost Point," The American Economic Review, XXXVIII (Decemben i947),910-918. 159 from calculable cost curves that reach the least—cost point at capacity to calculable cost curves that are constant in the normal Operating range. In both Of these cases the marginal cost curve never rises to meet the marginal revenue curve within the realm of reality, that is, normal Operating range. The idea Of a least~cost point at capacity and the constant marginal cost curves (within normal Operating range) stems from the previously mentioned statistical cost curves or at least from their implications. As a substitute for marginalism Professor Eiteman larings forth a theory Of inventory flows wherein changes Lin the movement Of inventories are used as the thermometer :fcu'price and output changes. Still the problem remains: irl a given case, is the businessman to choose a price change <31“ an output change? The choice here seems to necessitate ‘=C>st and revenue analysis in some form. The necessary afhalysis need not lead back to Strict marginalism and smOOth c3<1>St curves, but it dOes lead back to a fOrm Of incremental analysis which is not mentioned 'by Professor Eiteman. AIn addition to the calculability and applicability Of Cosyt curves there are two other issues involved in the con— troversy over marginalism. These issues are related to a . . - . Ct'-\-1al.buSiness behaVior and the problems concerning common 160 and joint costs. Studies Of actual business situations have indicated that price and output decisions are not made on the basis of an equality of marginal cost and revenue. A "full cost" concept is used, which starts from direct or prime costs and adds a percentage for factory overhead plus another percentage for profits which supposedly takes care of selling costs and interest on capital. There is no doubt that these percentages would fluctuate with demand conditions, so that the "full cost" concept has to be taken xmith a grain Of salt in terms Of its exact meaning. The "full cost" concept does in a sense bring out the ciifficulties of cost computation, especially in multiproduct industries where common and joint costs are encountered. 1Y3 inpute costs to individual products under such conditions brings on problems which challenge even the most vivid inmaginations. A l946 OPA report on cost accounting in industry which revealed that of 187,370 companies covered, Eipproximately 15 percent had total product costs on a unit baSis, illustrates at least to a certain extent the 14TR. L. Hall amd C. J. Hitch, "Price Theory and Business gehavior," Oxford Economic Papers, Number _2_ (May. 1939) x50rd At The Clarendon Press, Great Britain, 12—45. 161 difficulties Of cost computations.15 The total cost figures utilized most frequently spread selling and administrative costs to products on the basis Of relative sales, and mpread manufacturing overhead most frequently on the (many times questionable) direct labor cost basis. Such methods may have .given the CPA a cost figure for price control purposes, and also may have presented the companies with a usable figure for income tax return preparation and perhaps even for annual reports, but beyond these uses the utility Of such figures is very questionable. The matter of common and joint costs is rarely dis— crussed by economists,17 except to point out the difficulties CDf allocating these costs. As for accountants, the above (DEUX study clearly attests to their inability tO find a EDIYactical solution to such problems. 15 Martin Ii Black and Harold B. Eversole, A Report 92 S¥2§i§.Accounting in Industry, Accounting Department, Office Of iPlilce Administration (Washington: Government Printing Office, June, 1946), 68 pp. (mimeo) . 16A point to remember is that the CPA study is based °n~ian exceptional period--involving price controls when prticdng'(not efficiency) was the prime purpose Of costing. E3imilar study made in 1953 or 1958 might show different reshdlts. 7 Th R. A. Gordon, "Short-Period Price Determination in eOry and Practice, " The American Economic ReviewL XXXVIII (June,1948),273. 162 Fixed Costs and Volume Variation General Af first glance a discussion of fixed costs and volume variation would seem nonsensical. Fixed costs are costs that do not vary with volume, at least within broad ranges Of time and output. A lack Of functional relation— ship would seem tO indicate that there is no problem here. A closer look at fixed costs, however, indicates at least two fairly sizeable problems. One problem is a matter of terminology that has given rise to much confusion in the literature Of accounting and economics and tO a ssizeable controversy in academic and professional accounting (Zircles within recent years. The second problem is the very Scignificant role Of fixed costs in price discrimination as a Hueans of destructive competition. The terminology problem is related to a lack Of identifying marginalism as a matter of recognizing only StJfategic factors. When profit maximization is the goal, the Stlfiategic factors utilized in its implementation are the incremental items of cost and revenue. These are the only factOrs that count under such circumstances, but they are ruyt ‘therefore the only elements of cost and revenue. Failure 163 to label the strategic factors for what they are has resulted in the problems discussed below under fixed costs and economic waste. The possibility Of price discrimination brings forth problems concerning differential pricing in public utilities and private enterprise. In both public utilities and pri- vate enterprise the main issue concerning costs is the very difficult problem Of apportioning fixed costs to different classes Of customers. To prevent abuses and to provide liniformity Of treatment, government regulation is necessary .in public utility rate—making and in private enterprise. In tflie field of private enterprise, the government responds to Fuassible price discrimination via the Robinson—Patman Act alld.its cost justification requirement for price differentials. Tflie role of fixed costs in public utility rate—making and the inbinson—Patman Act will be used to buttress the comments which will follow concerning fixed costs and economic waste. Fixed Costs and Economic Wastel8 In many instances those who deal with marginalism Seen“ to ignorefixed costs and their real meaning. For \ 18 There are many forms of economic waste related to t . , . WSEE Unisallocation of resources, but as used here economic Ste includes only the non—use Of the capacity to produce prov:Lded by fixed costs. 164 example, throughout one very significant study is found the idea that with established plant and equipment, unit costs ordinarily depend on, among other things, the rate Of output.19 The same idea is also expressed frequently in a great deal Of literature as the spreading of fixed costs over more or less output, thereby either increasing or decreasing the fixed cost per unit. Although these ex- pressions seem to have some validity in their usual context, a more appropriate description would be "the utilization Of ‘vhat might otherwise be economic waste." The above comments might sound like rather superfiCial (Zriticisms if one did not encounter statements such as the following: It will be Observed that if marginal cost (added variable cost) is the whole cost Of each increment of output, then fixed C0858 could never become part Of the cost of product. The businessman, if not the economist, has accepted the accountant's miracle of converting X— 19 Cost Behavior and Price Policy, A Study Prepared by The Committee on Price Determination for the COWIference on Price Research (New York: National Bureau Of ECOnomic Research, 1943), 353 pp. 20Alfred Bornemann, "Empirical Cost Study and Egéiruomic Theory," The_AccountinggReview, XX (July,l945), 165 fixed cost into variable cost.21 Both of the above comments show some misunderstanding of economic events. Mr. Bornemann (if his statement is sincere) appears to have forgotten some Of the fundamental facts Of economic causation in that if economic factors are used, they cannot be treated as if they were unused-—as if they resulted in no product; in other words, their classi~ fication as fixed costs does not automatically relegate them to Oblivion. Comments like that Of Mr. Bornemann have in recent years led to a great output Of literature and con- 'troversy in accounting which will be discussed in Chapter Five. As for Professor Gordon's statement, it is only ruecessary to add the comment that no costs, however defined, Cuan be allocated or become costs Of product unless there is a. product to which to allocate them. Costs which do not liaad to product must be charged Off as losses, that is, they aJTe in.the category Of economic waste. Further, those costs W1‘1.1'.c:h_dl_glead to product are not waste, but have contributed \ lGordon, O . cit., 276. 22 ' St. C. Reinold Noyes, "Certain Problems in the Empirical N udy of Costs," The American Economic Review, Volume XXXI 0- 3 (September,l94l),482-86. " 166 economic value to the product. Utilized and unutilized fixed costs boldly outline the contrast between facilities made available and those utilized. These comments should illustrate that the accountant is not "converting" fixed costs into variable costs; he is merely calling a spade a spade when he recognizes unutilized capacity as a loss and utilized capacity as a cost Of product. The accountant's treatment Of fixed costs can be said, in effect, to make Iitilized capacity cost a product cost——and it is not EDarticularly important that this product cost be labeled "variable” or something else. It is still, in a very real Esense, a necessary cost Of production. What, to the writer, is unsound thinking, is also Cxontained at some points in the monumental work on Overhead Cszts by John Maurice Clark. He stated, in effect, that the -nEitural conclusion tO the statement that business is worth taking at anything more than its differential costs is that nothing but differential costs should be charged to pro— all 23 . . (rt. He added that if an accountant could isolate constant CcDSS‘ts from all others, he would have neither cost Of prC>duction nor idleness but Of readiness to produce, \ 23 John Maurice Clark, The Economics of Overhead S:~C->~§lE~-§_(Chicagoz The University Of Chicago Press, 1923), 25l. 167 regardless of whether there is any production or not.24 In other parts Of his work Mr. Clark seemed to change his mind and considered utilized fixed costs as costs Of production. When discussing inventory valuation he said, Making goods to stock increases the showing Of net income available for dividends by just the amount by which the book cost Of the goods exceeds the differential cost. However, this is not an evil, and since the books cannot charge total cost and differential cost goth, it seems more reasonable 2 to charge total cost. In a discussion Of public utility rate discrimination Iflr. Clark again revealed a tendency to consider utilized fixed costs as costs of product. He stated, The chief purposes of a rate system should be to earn a reasonable total return, tO develop the utmost use of facilities so long as every service pays at least its differential cost and tg gi§~ tribute residual costs fairly according :9 the responsibility 9; different E§§£§ :9; the amount 9f these costs.26 (italics mine) The assignment Of these residual or capacity costs to uSers is a problem that Mr. Clark spoke of over and over in hiES work, and most other authors do the same when speaking of Irate discrimination. Of primary importance for purposes \ 24 Ibid. 25ibid., 241. 261bid., 322. 168 of this discussion is the tacit admission in such cases that fixed costs are product costs if they grg ”tj]jzgd It may seem strange to belabor this point Of fixed costs and economic waste. TO appreciate fully the reasoning behind such stress it is necessary to bear in mind the problems Of accounting income measurement as well as identifying very specifically such items as economic waste for purposes Of full disclosure in financial statements. The loose language that has been used by both economists and accountants, especially with regard to "different costs for (iifferent purposes" (of which marginalism is an example), lias added confusion to already loose thinking in accounting circles . Economists might be wise to insert into their Ciiagramatic representations, especially in the realm of 'Tnanagerial economics,” the features of utilized capacity aruj economic waste. This same idea could also be reflected if! the usually over—simplified break—even chart. The problem is usually avoided by an implicit assumption that Satlfiis and production are equal. Introducing an inventory pro1=>lem by assuming an inequality in either direction Of 27See Chapter Five, pp. 238—9. 169 sales and production would force the economist and the break— even enthusiast into the position of considering fixed costs as either the costs Of a period or the costs of product. As shown above, they are costs Of product when utilized, and when unutilized they become period costs in the form Of economic waste. The whole key to this very real diagrammatic problem is to recognize the usual unrealistic implicit assumption of sales and production equality, and to change to an analysis that assumes inequalities. This was done, . . 28 at least in a hypothetical way, by Professor Brummet. TO close the preliminary discussion, it would perhaps IDe worthwhile to remember the words of C. Reinhold Noyes in YLis commentary on the phrase, "different costs for different FHeroses." It is chiefly loose language or loose, thinking; for what is meant is that, under various contingencies which may arise in connection with the processes Of production decisions by those responSible may be made without taking account of.all costs or even with reference to one or two categories only. That does not alter the fact Of costs. It does not make the items ignored or forgotten any the less costs. It is merely a way Of concentrating attention on the strategic factor in the case.2 28 R. Lee Brummet, derhead Costing, Op. cit., 83~lOO. 29Noyes, o . cit., 485. 170 Fixed Costs and Competition General Considering the fact that fixed costs do not vary with output, and that fixed costs are generally a measure of capacity to produce, the ordinary ups and downs Of business enterprise readily bring forth unutilized or excess capacity. This excess capacity is the source of discriminatory pricing policies and in some instances Of ruinous competition. The attitude Of our government towards price discrimination, as expressed in public utility regulations and the Robinson- .Patman Act, seems to be that fixed costs are a part Of the <:ost Of all production. In fact, the only reason for con-I ESidering fixed costs and competition With reference to public Lrtility and non-public utility industries is to show how 'tlie government has recognized the economics of fixed costs, 1 -e., fixed costs as truly part of production costs. The f'Ollowing paragraphs are intended to support the previous C3C>nc1usion30 that fixed costs must be considered costs Of EDIKDduction, at least to the extent that they are utilized. As for the discriminatory aspects of fixed costs, JXDTLn M” Clark recognized the situation long ago when he said: \ 30See page 168. 171 Existing business may or may not cover all overhead costs, but in either case, if there is spare capacity, added business will cause no added overhead and will be a gain at anything above differential cost, s9.lggg_§§ 33.232 §§.E§EE separate from existing business, so that existing earnings are not impaired. This leads to a system of making each separate section of the business pay the largest possible yield above differential cost. A 'section Of the business' may mean a single customer or a single sale, but in general, classification is limited by the extent to which business convenience makes it pracgicable or public sentiment makes it prudent. Such discriminatory pricing practices can result in ruinous competition if capacity Of fixed capital is wedded to a specific industry (special purpose equipment), if <:ompetitors are few, and if there is excess capacity in an Lindustry where fixed costs constitute a large portion Of txotal costs. In féct, the argument used to show how com— Fuatition will bring prices down to cost can also be used tO £3110w how competition will bring prices down further to (icifferential cost if excess capacity exists. Public Utility Industries The natural result Of fixed costs, or overhead costs ( tile economist ordinarily works with a concept Of overhead C‘?E§ts equivalent to fixed costs), has been numerous Lr1sytances Of cutthroat competition in all forms Of business. \ 31Clark, op. cit., 416. 172 Very early examples were the railroad rate wars. As a result Of such competition, state and federal governments began to institute various forms of regulation. Implied in these regulations is the idea that there is some way to allocate equitably the fixed costs to users. The regulatory laws did not say that discrimination per se was evil, but that there must be some just basis for discrimination. In the public utility industries there is a perfect example Of proportionately large fixed expenses and therefore the problems Of excess capacity and discriminatory pricing. .Again Mr. Clark clearly recognized the situation when he said, The problem of policy involved is twofold-- to stimulate Off—peak business in various ways and so improve the utilization Of the plant, and to apportiga justly the burdens that do not vary with output. There is (presumably) a just way to apportion the fixed CNSsts to output, and one Of the major problems Of our regulatory agencies is to work out a just apportionment, reicognizing-—at least in public utilities——that different EJIYDups Of users many times have more or less responsibility \ 32Clark, Op. cit., 15. 173 for different layers of capacity. The quantitative aspects are the real problem here, for very few will doubt the validity Of the concept of the just apportionment Of fixed or capacity costs. In the electric power industry an attempt is made to classify costs for rate making purposes as follows: Capacity costs--demand or readiness to serve costs ordinarily dependent on maximum daily demand. 1. 2. Output costs —-fuel, labor, and other costs necessary to generate power. Customer costs—~costs Of reading and maintaining meters as well as costs Of billing, collecting and maintaining customer accounts. 3. The classification is an attempt to categorize costs Enzcording to causal responsibility by customers or groups of Cnastomers. The above is just an example Of the problem of iafillocating costs in one industry. The problem is difficult and is sometimes complicated considerably as a result Of t1"1e fact that regulatory agencies overlook the basis of EECHDnomic causation Of costs. For example, in the telephone ilidiustry, the Bell system argues for company—wide rate-making, heiglecting cost differentials. Rates are desired on a principle wherein rate—making promotes maximum development of \ 33 . C: . . Martin G. Glaeser, Public Utilities in American 5* ltallSm (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1957), 421—22. 174 service by permitting the larger communities, in effect, to . . 34 . . subSidize the smaller. This concept of rate—making emphasizes certain social aspects of allocating costs which magnify immeasurably the complexities Of quantitative determination. Non-Public Utility Industries Industries without the confines of public utilities also must deal with fixed costs, excess capacity and dis- criminatory pricing. They are not plagued by ruinous or cutthroat competition to the extent that public utilities Inay be, due primarily to a difference in the ratio of fixed 1:0 variable costs. Here again, though, the federal govern— Dnent has stepped in to attempt a more just or equitable Eipportionment Of costs which at least implies that fixed (rests are part of the cost Of production. The Robinson—Patman Act Of 1936 is the vehicle Of ‘gtJvernment intervention. The section involved is Section 2(a), VVTIich gives rise to a cost proviso in cases where illegal EDITice discrimination is charged. This proviso gives the (ieifendant an Opportunity to defend a difference in price on .t}1e basis that his price differentials "make only due all-1C>wance for differences in the cost Of manufacture, sale (Dr- delivery resulting from the differing methods or quantities E:Ibidu 435—6. 175 in which such commodities aneto such purchasers sold or delivered”. From the inception Of the Act the intentions Of the Acts' proponents were quite Obvious with regard to the allocation of general overhead Of a fixed nature. The committees both Of the House and Of the .Senate discussed in their reports, in a general way, the concept Of cost which they had in mind in considering this act. The point Of most sig— nificance is that they seemed determined that general overhead should be allocated on a per- unit basis, and that pricing in terms Of the additional cost or increment involved in a particular order should not be permitted as justification for price discrimination. The above view of the rationale Of the Robinson— ]?atman Act is supported vigorously by Professor Taggart, (Ihairman Of an Advisary Committee on Cost Justification ' tn: the Federal Trade Commission.36 In a review of his Chommittee's report he said: 35 Willard J. Thorp, "Price Discrimination and Cost.' @e Journal _og Accountancy, LXIII (March,l937), 184. 36The Advisory Committee on Cost Justification was appointed by Federal Trade Commission Chairman Howrey in 1953 in order to help the commission develop guides for aclininistering the cost proviso Of the Robinson-Patman Act. £3 committee's report was rendered in February, 1956. 176 If anyone has hoped that this committee would give any aid or comfort to the marginal approach to cost justification, he will be disappointed. . . . The legislative history Of the Act and its Obvious intent are completely Opposed to the proposition that 'due allowance' has been made if only added costs are taken into account. ' The Act recognizes that all sales are responsible for the effect Of volume on costs, and therefore the first and the last customer should not be treated differently On the basis Of the fixed costs of production. If any customer is to be exempted from certain cost allocations it must be on the basis of some singular difference from other customers, such as a lack of benefit from the facilities or services thich are the key to the price differential. Furthermore, it :is incumbent on the seller to relieve all customers in a J.ike position from allocations Of the costs involved. The true position of the Robinscn-Patman Act is to Errotect small buyers from those large buyers who might try 'tID extort large discounts from those sellers who could be EDIJagued by a significantly high portion Of fixed costs. In effect, the law is an anti—price discrimination measure, in tliei sense that a system of price differentials must be \ 7 11' Herbert F. Taggart, "Cost Justification Under the rcfl31nson-Patman Act," The Journal of Accountancy, C l ‘JUne,1956), 54. 177 based on cost differentials. In this way the law has recognized an economic problem concerning the allocation Of costs, specifically overhead costs of a fixed nature. It is the law's intent to enforce a just means of apportioning overhead costs. The marginal or incremental approach is outlawed specifically. Both the laws regulating public utilities and the Robinson-Patman Act conclude, at least implicitly, that fixed costs are part Of the cost of all production. In addition to being described as an act proscribing unjustified price discrimination, the Robinson—Patman Act has been described by some as an unjustifiable outgrowth of the unjustifiable anti—chain store campaign of the 38 .1930's, and by others as an act which enforces price discrimination.39 Those who speak of the Robinson-Patman Zxct as an anti—chain store measure back up their arguments VVith.many statements made in Congressional hearings and 40 ‘tlie speech—making surrounding the Act. In addition there 8 Frederick M. Rowe, "Price Differentials and Product I)J.fferentiation: The Issues Under the Robinson-Patman Act," % Yale Law Journal,LXVI (November, 1956), 2-3. 39 - M. A. Adelman, "The Consistency of the Robinson- Pat”-rnan Act," The Stanford Law Review, VI (December,l953),3-22- 0 Frederick M. Rowe, loc. cit. 178 is Mr. Patman's admission that a Mr. Teegarden, counsel for the United States Wholesale Grocer's Association, actually wrote the bill.41 The only trouble with the anti—chain store approach to the Robinson—Patman Act is that the campaign is not recognized in its proper perspective. The anti—chain store campaign should be viewed as the radical answer to the discriminatory tactics of large buyers, while the Robinson—Patman Act should be viewed as the reasoned approach to prohibiting unjustified price dis— crimination. Professor Adelman champions the view that the Robinson—Patman Act enforces price discrimination. He points to inept administration of the act, and a few in— tsonsistent provisions of the act.42 However, Professor deelman would probably be quick to agree that the true irationale Of the act is to eliminate unjustifiable price Ciiscrimination. Inept administration is the key to Adelman’s Ciriticisms Of the Robinson—Patman Act. There is no doubt $131 the author's mind that Professor Adelman joins with many 41 Hearings Before the House Judiciary Committee on 533—118 to Amend the Clayton Act, 74th Congress, lst S ssion (1935), 9. ‘ 2 M. A. Adeleman, loc. cit. 179 others in hoping that the ultimate effect Of the reports rendered by the Committee on Cost Justification43 and the Committee to Revise the Anti-Trust Laws44 will be to pre- vent unjustified discriminatory pricing practices. Summary In economks all costs are usually categorized as to whether they are fixed or variable. Usually economists speak of overhead and fixed costs as synonyms, but the accountant includes in his overhead category both fixed and variable costs. The accountant recognizes that a large and increasing part Of his overhead is fixed, and that as production becomes Inore complex the variable element is of decreasing signifi— cance . The concept of a constant variable cost within the CDperating range would have to be interpreted with extreme (rantion (and perhaps even abandoned) in the case Of over— 1mead. This is true, since the idea involves all variable 43 Advisory Committee on Cost Justification, gpppgp pp .SEEEE Federal Trade Commission (Washington: Government Printing office, February, 1956) , 26 pp, (mimeo) . 44 Report pf the Attorney General's National Committee EL52§tudy the Antitrust Laws, (Washington: Government Printing Office, March,l955), 393 pp. 180 costs and the variable costs included in overhead are only a portion of the variable costs. Also, the variable costs other than in overhead usually include both of the other cost elements (direct labor and direct materials) which are more than likely of a constant unit cost nature. It is probably, under these circumstances, that the reason for constancy of total variable unit costs is the preponderance of direct labor and direct materials which would Offset to a large extent any lack of constancy in variable overhead costs. In other words, the constancy of variable unit costs may well be an averaged constancy. There is nothing inherent in the-statistical cost studies or the idea of variable fixed inputs that would vitiate such a conclusion. Overhead, by definition, would include all fixed czosts which, due to their increasing significance, must be (zonsidered an important phase of any study of overhead., This 1.8 especially true when a fluctuating production volume <3)€3rformance in terms of functional divisions and subdivisions. tr'he determination of the firm goals in an overall sense as “”6111 as in the many unavoidably delicate and intricate details 1‘3 usually considered the planning function of management. 183 Closely related to planning is the control function, or that function which is intended to make actual results conform to plans. In accounting the actual cost and revenue accumulations must be related to the benchmarks, anticipations, or goals which have been set up, in order to perform the function of comparison which is designed to ferret out and eliminate waste. The comparison and correction function, of which accounting is a part, is essentially the control function. In addition to the planning and control functions there is still one major task in which accounting accumu— lations should be of aid. This is the decision—making function. In the broadest sense this is the function that selects the path to follow or the goals to be achieved from iamong the many alternatives available. Planning is in Gassence both preliminary to and the result of the decision— nnaking process. Planning involves such tasks as determining tflue means and methods necessary to achieve goals, the necessary IEEacilities, manpower and other factors of production. De- <2isions to act must be made before the plan for acting is c3C>mplete, and at the same time a plan is being carried out it nnuStbe constantly and continuously challenged in order to reCheck the original choice among alternatives as well as to, 184 allow for the introduction of new alternatives which may or may not be introduced into a new and revised plan. If accounting data is to be of any value in the performance of the above functions, those who accumulate the data must be familiar with the functions they intend to serve.1 This is the only approach that will maintain for accounting data any semblance of utility. It is the only approach that will aid the responsible executive in achieving his goals. In accordance with the goals of this dissertation, control of overhead costs will receive special emphasis in the general discussions that will follow in this chapter. .First, financial and cost accounting will be considered in Llight of how they can aid in the achievement of managerial ggoals. Then management views on fixed overhead costs will kDe considered in order to illustrate certain aspects of fiixed overhead costs which will be worked into the concepts 1 . For excellent statements on this point of view see, R. H. Coase, ”Business Organization and the Accountant, :Lr1C1uded in David Solomons (ed. ) Studies in Costing (London: SWeet and Maxwell Ltd. 1952), 105— 6. Verne Breitenbucher, "Putting Cost Accounting to Work — FVDIT Cost Control," National Association of Cost Accountants' )(e\arbook 1946,112. 185 of income measurement in Chapter Five. Financial Accounting As A Management Tool Financial accounting is that area of accounting which revolves around the measurement of income. The income is determined periodically, at least annually, and is portrayed in an income statement which is usually accompanied by a balance sheet. In the income statement the information presented consists of gross income, the various deductions therefrom and the net income figure. In the balance sheet are listed various categories of assets and equities. Granting the existence of changing price levels and the necessary corrections therefore,of what values are the statements of financial accounting? Can the individual items EDresented in the statements or any combination of them be liseful in the various phases of the internal management of Ein industrial enterprise? To answer these questions three important features C>ffinancial accounting must be recognized. These are as ffOllows: l) the statements prepared are very summarized presentations. 2) the statements are prepared from a long-run point of view 186 3) the statements are "outsider oriented". Summarized Data The summarization of accounting data in the financial reports yields only very general data concerning Operations; ‘this is especially true of published financial reports. VVithin the confines of a particular organization, the fin— eancial reports are in effect unsummarized to yield more :Lnformative data. The summarized versions are very general iJIdeed, and can only yield information of an overall nature 'Mfliile at the same time they can hide or average out Of sight aniny significant items. Information concerning the con— tributive effect of individual divisions, plants, or CHepartments as well as product lines or products is completely 1“iciclen in the summary presentations of financial accounting. Wi thout the more detailed data and other information which there 1‘3 <3rdinarily considered the realm of cost accounting, 15‘ ‘very limited managerial utility in the reports of f in ancial accounting . Long-Run Assumption In addition to the summary aspects Of financial a _ _ ‘ . . (:Ciounting, the long-run pOint of View is ever—present and 187 is in reality a vital feature of financial accounting. The foremost example of this is the accounting for fixed assets. Accrual accounting is, by its very nature, ijlong- run significance. This long—run idea is perfectly illustrated lay the going-concern concept inherent in financial accounting. 'The going-concern concept assumes that the enterprise is not in danger of voluntary or involuntary cessation of activities. 'Iherefore under some circumstances incurred costs are Eiccumulated as investments in the future (assets) until such tzime as the investments bear fruit in the form of revenue. ZXt.that time the investments become expenses, and are Eisssociated or matched with the revenue they gave rise to in CDrder to yield a net income figure. Such is the nature of aC=<:'rua1 accounting, which is inextricably associated with ‘tflea going-concern or long—run outlook of financinal accounting. The fact that reports of financial accounting can be prEspared for periods much shorter than a year should not ‘leééid.anyone to believe that such statements are prepared from ' a. Sshort—run point Of View. It takes more than working wifli S‘tICDrtuperiods to reflect a short—run point of view. The $11(Drt—run as such demands an incremental point of View and recognition of the relationships between costs and output. lq<3vfhere in financial accounting are these short—run 188 characteristics found,2 and since the various internal management functions necessitate both a short and a long—run point of view the presentations of financial accounting are not at all adequate for management use. This is es- pecially true in the case of manufacturing firms where the Inyriad activities of the factory are summarized into a cost (of goOds sold figure. Outsider Orientation Foremost of all the criticisms of financial accounting, \ 111 terms of its utility for internal management, is the fact ‘tliat financial accounting is “outsider oriented”. The EDITesentations are intended primarily for the use of outsiders 2See the section on cost accounting (pp.214-23).for a. Ciiscussion of recent proposals concerning the introduction CNE' short—run characteristics into the financial accounting f ramework . _ 3Outsider orientation is considered by A. C. Littleton lr‘ his Structure pf Accounting Theory, American Accounting ASssiociation Monograph No. 5., 1953, on pages 79—81, in terms ‘31? the stockholders and financial statements as reports of Inaflagerial stewardship. The cornerstone of the public ac:Clounting profession, that is, independence and the heCzessity of financial statement certification to third parties, also indicates without doubt the outsider Or'ientation of financial statements. 189 such as tax collector, the banker, the security analyst, as well as current and prospective investors. This external orientation is actually what leads to the two previously- considered features of financial accounting. Details concerning individual parts of the enterprise or its products, as well as the short—run or incremental features of certain aspects of business, are considered confidential information. As such they are not to be considered as part of the end products of financial accounting, which are intended for the use of outside parties in order that they may judge the overall effectiveness or profitability or progress of a business enterprise during a particular period of time. Peter F. Drucker recognized the limitations of ftnancial accounting as an aid to internal management when he stated . . .we have to focus accounting data on management's needs in running a business rather than on the requirements of a tax collector and banker, or on the old wives' tale so many investors imbibe at their security analyst's knee and forever after mistake for financial wisdom.4 4 Peter F. Drucker, Tpp Practipp 9: Management (New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1954), 72. 190 Measure of Economic Progress Financial accounting as described thus far has very serious limitations in terms of internal managerial utility. There is, though, one way in which it can yield some internally useful data, that is, by providing an overall or summarized measure of econqmic progress. The measure is the income figure, or, as Littleton said, "the center of gravity“ around which all of financial accountinglrevolves.5 Management, in addition to desiring details as to the in- dividual elements of an enterprise, also is in need of a consolidated point of View which shows the overall results of the firm's efforts during a particular period of time. Effie results or progress in one period could easily be used for comparative purposes. Comparisons of relative economic prOgress could be made between periods, similar firms, industry averages and perhaps even economy averages. These comparisons could be made in terms of the net operating income figure or of the summarized presentations of revenue or expenses. In the following pages, the idea of financial accounting data as a measure of economic progress will be integrated into that overall framework designed to provide 5Littleton, o . cit., 18-35. 191 managers with useful accounting accumulations. As for the breakdowns Of overall progress, this is usually the province of cost accounting. The need for details concerning the progress or contributive effect of enterprise subdivisions must be recognized, as well as details suited to the short—run point of view with its related categories and classifications Of cost. With these changes the external orientation of financial accounting is replaced by, or at least supplemented with, an internal orientation. The next section on cost accounting is intended to show how more useful data can be prepared. 'Financial accounting has been found wanting except for the presentation of an overall report of economic progress. Cost Accounting As a Management Tool The field of factory cost accounting can be sub- divided into two broad categories. In the first category c0st accounting can be considered as simply an extension of financial accounting, while in the second category cost accounting can take on a more intensive and searching review of the individual elements of the factory in a manner that is not at all apparently related to financial accounting. In this section primary emphasis will be on the factory costs, 192 for it is factory overhead that is the main concern of this dissertation. Extension of Financial Accounting Perusal of many cost accounting texts6 could easily lead one to believe that the major or sole purpose of cost accounting is the determination of a unit cost figure to be utilized in inventory valuation for balance sheet purposes, and for measuring the cost of goods sold for income statement purposes. In effect, such works are interested primarily in cost accounting only for the purpose of filling the gaps in financial accounting which result from the fact that an enterprise manufactures all or some of the products it sells “Hither than purchasing all of its products complete and ready to sell. Cost accounting in such instances is only a means Of providing the equivalent of a purchase price figure. This approach has the same inherent limitations as financial accounting for internal management purposes, except that it does show or bring out some of the details. The 6An outstanding example of a text which does not follow this pattern is: Carl T. Devine, Cost Accounting and Analysis (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1950), 752 pp. 193 long-run approach and the outsider orientation are still predominant. As for the idea of utilizing the income statement as a measure of economic progress, certain very useful accumulations are possible, dependent on whether historical or predetermined costs are used. Historical Costs Versus Predetermined Costs By historical costs is meant the accumulation of cost data on the basis Of what actually happened in the factory. There is no comparison between what did happen and what should have happened. The only comparison possible is between what happened at this time or period and what happened in the past. Such a comparison brings out only the overall extent of progression or regression between actual occurrences. The yardstick used to measure progress is not based on what should have occurred; it is based on what did occur at one time. Obviously then, there are inherent limitations to historical costs. This is what was on the mind of Harrington Emerson many years ago when he wrote that there were two ". . . radically different methods of ascertaining costs..."7 7 Harrington Emerson, "Efficiency as A Basis for Operations and Wages, Part IV, The Modern Theory of Cost Accounting,"The Engineering Magazine, XXXVI (D cember,l908), 336. 194 The first method determined what costs were after completion of the work, while the second method determined what costs should be before actual work was undertaken. The first method erred, since it delayed valuable information and, even more important, it combined the costs of inefficiency with costs as they should have been. The second method divided costs into "standard expense" and "avoidable loss", and thus facilitated the elimination of readily identified waste.8 With the introduction of standard costing as pre- sented by Emerson, financial statements could be prepared, at least for internal purposes,9 in such a way that deviations from expected results were highlighted.) Thus the results of operations for period were, in effect, compared with results as they should have occurred, and, furthermore, comparison of periodic reports could yield a more accurate determination of the direction and extent of progress. Standard costing then added to the concept of financial accounting as an 8 Ibid., 336—9. 9Standard cost variations are never a part of exter- nal financial reporting, due to the confidential nature of such information. 195 overall measure Of economic progress the idea that manage— ment would be shown not only the profits i: dig gpkp, but also what happened to the pgofits that i: should have made.10 The standard cost variations are generally broken down into price and quantity variances for direct material and direct labor, and budget, efficiency and capacity variances for overhead. Price variances measure the difference between prices actually paid for the elements of production and standard or expected prices. Quantity variances measure the difference cost—wise between quan- tities actually used and quantities that should have been used in producing certain volumes of output. The overhead laudget variance is essentially a price variance, while the CTverhead efficiency variance is essentially a quantity VEiriance. The overhead capacity variance is actually a Itleasure of idle facilities, or that portion of fixed manufacturing overhead which has not been productively utliclized when practical capacity is used as the measure of Capacity. When normal or cycle capacity is utilized the \ 10 This is the view of G. Charter Harrison, often COnSidered the father of standard costing. Iéae5= G. Charter Harrison, "Working Plans for Standard Costs— :[33 Obtaining Real Value from the Cost System," Management Eafliiineering'lll (August,l922), 98. 196 meaning Of the capacity variance changes. Under normal capacity, the overhead capacity variance represents fixed overhead costs recovered in selling prices of this period which will not have to be recovered in the :future (overabsorbed), or fixed overhead costs not re- czovered in selling prices of this period but which will have ‘to be recovered in the future (underabsorbed). Under cycle <:apacity, the overhead capacity variance represents fixed (overhead costs applicable to current revenue which will be anid for in the future (overabsorbed), or fixed overhead (costs applicable to future revenue (underabsorbed). In addition to the use of these variances for illustrating in a very dramatic fashion what happened to EDrOfitS that should have been made, there are many who recommend the use of such variances for cost control, that is the elimination of waste or deviations from plans or I EStandards. Waste elimination is of course the idea behind Ehuerson's statements,12 and waste elimination is still 11 For a complete discussion of these concepts see tile section in Chapter Two on ”The Sequel To The Supplementary 12Emerson, o . cit., 336. 197 emphasized in cost accounting texts and actual accounting practice as the major goal of standard costing.l3 The use of such variances for cost control is pre- dicated on analyses which determine the causes of the \rariances as well as responsibility for the variances. VVithout these analyses cost control through variances would k>e ineffectual. In the case Of direct materials and direct ILabor, the causes and responsibilities for variances can be aassessed with relative ease and procedures can be instituted 1:0 correct variations not caused by changing conditions. As for overhead, the variances accumulated leave much ‘to be desired for internal management purposes. Overhead (or indirect manufacturing expenses represent a considerable ‘variety of items which cannot be or are not worthwhile ‘tracing to a particular product or batch of products. The fsetting of standards related to unit overhead costs is an éiveraging process in which so many individually different Zitems are averaged that the efficacy of the standards tlihemselves is questionable, let along the variances from sStandards. Such standards might be the most reasonable way 13 . ' How Standard Costs Are Being Used Currently (New York: National AssociatiOh of Cost Accountants, 1950), 26-50. 198 ‘to approximate a unit overhead cost to fulfill the require— Inents of financial accounting, but that is all.14 Accounting for overhead costs is the area wherein one is forced to :recognize the inadequacies of cost accounting when it is (iirected towards fulfilling the requirements of financial accounting. Professor R. S. Edwards recognized this point very eaxplicitly when he stated that the purpose of costing is t:o shed light on constantly recurring management problems. fie added in a very cynical fashion that to too many accountants tihe inclusion of all costing procedures within the confines "16 (Df double—entry is "the hallmark of respectability. They (30 not realize that the enormous drawback to a double-entry czosting system is that some arbitrary assumptions have to be . 17 Set up to make it workable. These assumptions relate EDrimarily to overhead allocations, wherein managerial utility 14 Ibid., 49. This study concludes that those who do (accumulate overhead budgets and variances use them primarily for costing production, that is, accumulating inventory figures rather than for cost control. 15 R. S. Edwards, "The Rationale of Cost Accounting," included in David Solomons (Ed.),Studies in Costing (London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952), 88. —_ _— 16 , Ibid., 100. 17 _ Ibid., 91. 199 iS sacrificed for the double-entry framework of financial accounting . With this limitation in mind, it is no wonder that (zost accumulations in terms of responsibility have been aadvocated for so long. These accumulations are outside of 'the double-entry framework and many times include all the ealements of factory costs in addition to overhead costs. 'rhe next section is reserved for a discussion of respon- ssibility accounting. Responsibilipy Accounting Facilitation of factory operations should be the nnajor goal of industrial accounting. To operate the factory {plans are needed, which must be put into effect, and finally ‘the operations must be controlled in accordance with the Enlans. The essence of the problem of industrial accounting is then the determination of what information is necessary . . 18 for the planning and control of factory operations. 18 . Planning and control are the two categories Suggested for cost analyses in the "Tentative Statement of Cost Concepts Underlying Reports for Management Purposes" jby’the Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards of the z\merican Accounting Association. See The Accounting Review, XXXI, (April, 1956), 184. 200 Since plans are based primarily on forecasts of future conditions, it is necessary to consider costs as 'they will most likely be at such future times. Also, since ‘there is the problem of assuring that the elements of pro— ciuction will be present when needed, the relationships between czost and volume must be brought into perspective. In the first place, certain future commitments are made on the loasis of forecasts which result in a relatively inflexible relationship between cost and volume. .This inflexibility recognizes the fact that commitments made for the future \vill lead to the incurring of some unavoidable costs within ‘the confines of the present planning period. An inflexible relation between costs and volume brings out the short—run <:Onsiderations of fixed and variable costs and the related flexible budget for planning purposes. In other words, in addition to standards and plans based on sound forecasting, it is absolutely necessary to recognize the relationship of costs, to output in order to be prepared to manage the fixed and variable factors of production more accurately. There— fore, for planning purposes, costs must be considered in terms of volume (fixed and variable) as well as in terms of future expectations concerning prices, efficiencies, and even management attitudes. 201 In addition to future expectations and volume con— ssiderations, if the planning and control phases of management aare to operate effectively the plan must recognize cost (zontrollability. This means that planning must recognize ‘the organization structure (the real structure, not riecessarily the formal paper structure), for if control is t:o be effective it must pinpoint responsibility. The concept of expense controllability was recognized aas long ago as 1919 by G. Charter Harrison, a contemporary (of many early management pioneers as well as one of the most ealoquent and persistent advocates of standard costing. His relevant comments were so lucid that they must be quoted. "It is quite Obvious that for a cost system 'to enable the superintendent to know whether or not he is doing the work he is responsible for as economically as possible' it is necessary for us to distinguish between expenses for ‘which the superintendent is directly responsible and those over which he has no control...”19 Controllability OWfl'CostS is a matter of level in the organizational hierarchy. All costs are controllable at Some level; thus even the summarized statements of financial 19 G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting in the New Industrial Day," Industrial Management,LVIII (December,l919),443. 202 aaccounting can be considered as fairly adequate overall Ineasures of managerial ability or stewardship. At lower Inanagement levels some costs begin to assume uncontrollable garoportions. A perfect illustration is when high level eexecutives commit the company and its subdivisions to eaxpenditures on the basis of decisions affecting the future; for example, depreciation, taxes, and insurance on real EDrOperty which are the result of high—level expenditure (decisions. The high—level executives are responsible for 'these costs even though for purposes of computing a total unit <:ost they are chargeable to an operating subdivision. The concept of cost controllability is nothing more than fitting the system of internal accounting to the organization structure. Planning for future periods involves a build—up of estimated future costs by areas of respon- sibility. These areas of responsibility should extend as far down in the organization structure as responsibility extends, at least to the foreman level. Only in this way can cost control be effective. Under such a system plans must, in effect, relate the incurring of costs to personal responsibility. In the Case of a foreman, he should be charged with all those <205ts in his activity center over which he has control. 203 These costs would include direct labor, direct materials, supplies and some forms of indirect labor. He would not be held responsible for such items as depreciation on equipment, taxes, and utilities such as heat, which are controlled by managerial policy and other external conditions. Someone above the foreman is responsible for the depreciation, PrOperty taxes and other costs not controllable at the foreman level. Costs such as depreciation and property taXes are controllable by those who make long—run commit— ments and purchase the depreciable property. Service department costs such as maintenance present a problem in assessment of responsibility. The service department manager is responsible for all costs over which he has control, but at the same time, since operating fore— men can request maintenance work, they also are responsible fOr maintenance costs. This common situation where at leaSt two persons are responsible for costs must be faced ScJuarely. If both the Operating foreman and the service de[Dartment manager are able to influence the cost through their own actions, they should both be held responsible. In this way the operating foreman would be forced into that heCessary position of balance between requests for main- teriance and continuity of efficient production. The rule 204 here is to. charge a man with cost responsibility if he is able to exert a significant influence on the cost.20 Of course, in the case of a factory, cost plans must be based on a forecast of sales and on inventory policy in order tobuilde estimates of production. In order to allow for the possibility of variations in expected sales and the effect of such variations on production, the plan adopted takes the form of aflexible budget, which is a Plan that recognizes that certain costs change with volume Va r iat ions . The control that comes with cost planning related '10 responsibility is a matter of communicating information to responsible people about the desires of management, and at the same time motivating responsible peOple by giving t”—l'lem goals. There is also the desireability of comparing actual and expected performance in order to determine out-of- line performance which can be eliminated in the future. These thI‘ee aspects of control, that is, communication, motivation, ‘ and checking—up are those considered important by the American Accounting Association's Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards . \ Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards Of the American Accounting Association, _qp. cit., 189. 21 Ibid., 188-190 . L;%_ 205 It is unfortunate that the committee did not integrate tliese ideas more closely and also that it did not drop the zapnoroach of “checking up“ as simply a matter of improving :ftrture performance. 'The desired integration in cost control its a matter of informing those responsible for costs as to What is expected of them, thus motivating them to attain taa

ectations, since they should be aware of the fact that 't}1€3 attainment of expectations is their job. Then management Cfiara compare actual and expected results not only in order ‘tCD find out what went wrong so that future problems may be eliminated, but primarily in order to find out what went “firwong and what has already been done to correct out-of-line c(Draditions. A truly integrated cost control system is the Slllsject of Chapter Six. Assumed throughout this discussion C>f7 responsibility accounting is the cooperation and approval (3f? those men who are to be held responsible in the setting ‘JF> of their segment of the total plan. The above View of responsibility accounting is quite Sehparate and distinct from the traditional accounting EDITflolems of income measurement. This distinction does not mean that profit goals have been relinquished; in fact, it means quite the opposite, for emphasis is focused on profit rmaximization. This seeming paradox is simply explained by 206 tflie fact that there is quite a difference between working 'tcxnard profit maximization and the periodic measurement Of Earxofit. Every day-to—day effort of the enterprise should fc>cus attention on profit maximization in the sense of lL1t.ive effect is measured only in terms of costs and IT€!Venues over which people have control. In the case of ‘tliee factory, which is of primary interest here, revenue is of 1'1C) significance since factory personnel rarely if ever have arljyaffect on revenue as such. The factory personnel are affected primarily by cost, in terms of making it conform to EDIWsdetermined limits and expending efforts (research and me‘thods development) to reduce the predetermined limits. Other Aspects of Cost Accounting: Pricing There is no doubt that costs do have a place in the E3rocess of price determination. As pointed out in Chapter 'PwO , the origin of cost accounting for overhead was related 207 aJJnost exclusively to price setting. In such cases direct Inerterial and direct labor costs were accumulated and a Eaexrcentage was added to cover manufacturing overhead, <2cnnmercial and administrative costs, and the hoped—for profit. TQlEE percentage used was actually a rule Of thumb percentage. With the advent of competitive conditions there was a IUCDITe searching and scientific analysis of costs utilized to hndtild up to selling prices,22 and at the same time there were 'tT1case who were propounding a selling price ideology based on a. czost existent under efficient conditions. In other words wEisstes, whether related to unused or wasted facilities or to <3t:}1er production waste (labor and materials), were to be e>{c21uded in setting prices that would tend toward industrial tranquility.23 At about the same time there were those who began to as Sume an even more sophisticated approach to pricing. Thease were the men who spoke in terms of a price being given 13}’ an autonomous market, cost being used merely as a 22See A. Hamilton church. The. Eraser Distrihution. of. 'figflpgnse Burden (New York: The Engineering Magazine Co., 1908), 1L6 pp. 23H. L. Gantt, "The Relation Between Production and (30sts," Transactions pg the American Sociepy g; Mechaniggl lingineers, XXXVII (June,1915 Meeting), 128. 208 determinant of whether or not production shOuld be under— taken. This point of View took two lines of thought. One was related to a long—run situation involving complete pro- duct costs (including a share of fixed overhead)24 while the other involved the short-run situation and partial pro- duct costs of an incremental nature (excluding fixed OVerhead) . Today all of these ideas are still with us, and together they form a rather complete picture concerning 'tllee way various individuals look upon price determination. The Office of Price Administration of World War II and the Office of Price Stabilization of the Korean War illustrate the idea of utilizing all costs to build up to a Selling price. There is some question as to how scientific the build-up was, for the CPA did recommend the use of highly 24 B. A. Franklin, "Cost Methods that Give the EXecutive Control of His Business — VI The Vexing Question if Expense," The Engineering Magazine, XLIII (June,l912), 28. I 25 , Ibid. George 0. May, "Cost Accounting, " Twenpy—five Years p_f_ qunting Responsibility 1911-1936 (New York: The American Institute Publishing Co., Inc., 1936), 364. 209 questionable methods in apportioning manufacturing overhead as well as commercial and administrative costs.26 Re— negotiation of government contracts seems to insist on costs under efficient conditions and a normal profit. These ideas, taken in conjunction with labor's expressed views on normal profits, management's expressed rationale for price ir1<2reases and the emphasis on cost—price relationships in recent years as a result of the inflationary spiral, indicate a. Itather pronounced view among many people that cost and E>Iiices are closely tied together. An example of the connection between efficient costs alici prices was provided by Howard Greer when he said: "Much as we may desire to realize a price which will CKDrnpensate us for our costs, justified or unjustified, we Cfiirlnot expect our customers to pay us a premium to cover ifleafficiency, wastefulness or disadvantageous position."27 26The recommended method for allocating selling and 'aéhninistrative costs to different products was relative Salles volume. For manufacturing overhead, the (many times qué'stionable) direct labor cost method was recommended. See: Martin L. Black and Harold B. Eversole, A Report 92 S¥E§t Accounting in Industry, Accounting Department, Office of PlZ‘ice Administration (Washington: Government Printing Office, JWlne,1946) 68 pp. (Mimeographed). 27Howard Greer, "Cost Factors in Price-Making," The kfiirvard Business Review, XXX (July-August.l952), 43. 210 The idea of an autonomous price which will govern ‘ufliether or not production is to be undertaken is still found t:cxday. Under autonomous prices there can be no such thing at; a cumulative cost computation to set a price. Pricing sstuarts from the consumer's wants and purchasing power, and earnfls with the task of finding a means of satisfying the (:cxnsumer's wants within the limits of his purchasing power. 'IQIIJS, under autonomous pricing, society's "consuming <3!3;oartment" places orders with its "producing department", ‘311Ci it is the task of the executive to keep the plants going 53C) that the orders may be filled.28 As for the incremental or marginal View of pricing, tifiis has been pretty much the domain of the economist. In r<3<3ent years, though, this concept has been under heavy at‘tack from the point of view of inability to determine InEirg’inal revenue as well as from the point of view of a c:Ol'lstant marginal cost within the realm of normal output expectations. Under either of these conditions marginal re-‘Venue and marginal cost would never meet and establish a p'i‘ice of output in the short—run.29. 8Jules Backman, Price Practices and Price Policies (New York: The Ronald press Co., 1953), 145—46. 29See the "Marginalist Controversy" in Chapter Three, pP~158-62. 211 A review of cost and pricing literature shows that ixieas do not change too much over the years. In actual EqITicing practice today there is involved some kind of a czcnnbination of all of the above ideas. Hall and Hitch came 'tC) the conclusion, on the basis of their studies, that 13Llsinessmen based their prices on cost plus a percentage to CZCTver manufacturing overhead and another percentage to cover CYtlaer expenses and profit.30 Offhand it looks as if we are lDéicmLWMere we started from in the beginning, except that ‘tlleere are two add—on percentages rather than one. A closer EiE>§maisa1 would indicate that no percentages are quantified, and that the total percentage added on is subject to change rwofit percentage is undoubtedly present, to some degree 1Dth it is not absolute. The above approach based on the Hall and Hitch studies 153 quite realistic when one considers the many common and jCDint costs of a fixed and variable nature (most of these are overhead items) that are ever—present in the usual ITu-llti—product, multi—process business firm. To allocate such 3 0R. L. Hall and C. J. Hitch, "Price Theory and BUsiness Behavior," Oxford Economic Papers, Number g,(Mayll939), OXford At The Clarendon Press, Great Britain, 12-45. 212 cxosts requires a great deal of judgment, but at the same ‘thne it must be recognized that all allocation methods are airfloitrary. Therefore every element in the cost—plus pricing ‘teachnique must be taken with at least one grain of salt. IDj.fficulties in cost allocation, especially overhead, yield TliJghly subjective cost figures, and difficulties in assessing ‘tluea status of the market lead to a highly subjective adding— C>r1 of percentages of profit. These conclusions related to the Hall and Hitch SStIUdies, are consistent with other studies of cost—price Ifealationships. A 1948 National Association of Cost Accountants' S”tJde showed that most of the 72 companies surveyed used ‘ Sfitiandard manufacturing costs as a basis for prices. Such Standards were based on, or converted to, expected input F>ITices, and unavoidable variations from standards were also tliea subject of special adjustments.31 Judgment enters into ‘t}1ius pricing scheme not only in setting standards, but also 1“ Inaking adjustments thereto for pricing purposes. In . acaddition it should not be forgotten that the largest area rfiquiring judgment is the percentage to add to standard miinufacturing costs in order to yield a selling price. This 31 How Standard Costs Are Being Used Currently (New ‘York: National Association of Cost Accountants,1952), 73. 213 leeads us unavoidably back to the results of the Hall and 32 Iijgtch study. A somewhat more pertinent study by the National Ikensociation of Cost Accountants would certainly give some ssenuse of relief to the marginalist. In this study the CZCnnpanies involved separated costs into fixed and variable Eilxements. However, the separation was not for the purpose CDfE a marginal pricing scheme. The fixed and variable break— Cicymms were utilized to recognize the relations between costs, \7C>1ume, and profit in such a way that within the range of E>C>ssible prices and the quantities of product that could be E5C>1d at such prices, the most profitable combination of cost, \7C31ume, and profit could be approximated.33 Fixed costs (a 1-arge element of overhead) are basic factors in the price EsCheme uncovered by this study. These conclusions on the utility and use of a fixed—variable cost breakdown are in agreement with a recent survey of pricing practices by the 32 Hall and Hitch, loc. cit. ————. 33N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 23, "Direct Costing," WBulletin. XXIV, Sec, 3.(April,l953), 1108-1110. SQe also: . Alwyn M. Hartogensis, "The Art and Practice of I-’ricing:" N.A.A. Bulletin, XXIX,Sec. 1.(March,1958), 63-74. ‘ 214 IDaItnell Corporation.34 In summary it might be said in the first place that 'tliere is some relationship between costs and prices. The rrelationship should and does concern expected costs, not past ()1? historical costs. Secondly, it is wise to segregate ftixed and variable costs, but not for the purposes of a nnairginal pricing scheme which might be relied upon under cieepmessed conditions, in obtaining a one—time sale, or in CDgiposition to the Robinson—Patman Act. The fixed—variable sseagregation is exceedingly useful in judging cost—volume- E>1rcfifit.relationships applicable to a range of prices eaestablished by competitive conditions in order to consider HICDIe adequately the effect of volume on costs and, of course, (Dr! profits. Other Aspects of Cost Accounting: Decision Making In the broad category of decision—making, cost data E‘ITE of great significance. Decisions in a business enterprise 51113 most apprOpriately influenced by incremental costs and reP-‘venues. The word "incremental" does not necessarily ixldicate a marginal approach, for in many decisions fixed 4"Pricing Techniques and Practices Today: A Surveyg' :The Management Review'LXVI (MayIl957), 8—9. 215 cxosts do become incremental in nature. Capital expenditure decisions must necessarily rtecognize added fixed and variable costs as increments. bdefluld eliminate many costs fixed by policy as well as by tLiJne, such as maintenance, insurance, and all the costs of IDLJilding occupancy, just by disposing of the property that Vveas.previously used to manufacture. A decision to make, on 1:}1e other hand, should recognize that manufacturing facilities nFillst be replaced. Pricing decisions also must recotnize fixed costs, ‘3><>licy, and level of output. The idea of basing management decisions on a simple IDJTeakdown of costs into fixed and variable components is EDCDpular with the advocates of "direct costing", which (as tifiey say) is nothing more than recognizing that costs are E23.ther fixed or variable.36 The direct costing approach to c3ecision-making fails to recognize that fixed costs must be c3C>nsidered in making decisions, that the costs of significance 3LT} decision—making are not yesterday's costs, but are the ‘3<>Sts being incurred or avoided today and costs to be in- <2urred or avoided in the future, and, finally, that each (3EH2ision must be based on an independent study of how the For this View see: Jonathan N. Harris, "Case Against Administrative EIIXpenses,” The Journal of Accountangy, LXXXII (JulyIl946). 32—6. "- Raymond P. Marple, "Direct Costing and the Uses <3f Cost Data," The Accounting Review,XXX (July.1955), 432—3. 6 Marple, Ibid., 431-2. 217 CNDSt factors behave. There is no method that will fit all cnases or even most cases. The incremental approach to cienzision—making must be considered in its broadest sense, tliat is, added costs no matter what their relation is to \rcylume in the short-run. Accounting for manufacturing overhead is, without CJLzestion, of great significance in decision-making. In fact, C>\7erhead is the category of costs usually emphasized in "Ciirect costing”, since direct labor and materials are con— Esj.dered variable. Overhead includes a great variety of costs C>ff varying variability and varying fixity, as well as costs VVTIich are extremely difficult, if not impossible, to trace thD particular units of product or those categories applicable t1C) decision-making. These considerations alone should make cDrIe quite wary of any suggestion that a breakdown of over— 1dead costs into fixed and variable components is all that is heieded for decisionwmaking. An attempted breakdown of 37 The usual techniques recommended for the breakdown fo costs into fixed and variable components are: 1. Visual inspection of accounts 2. Statistical analyses 3. Engineering studies to determine how costs should vary. For a complete explanation see: N,A,c,A, Research Series, No. 16 "The Variations of Costs With Volume," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXX,,Section 3. (June 15, 1949), 1228-36. 218 caverhead costs into fixed and variable categories would iiivolve a highly questionable averaging technique after a cieacision was made as to the definition of fixed costs. this is meant that a variable overhead rate would be an I3)’ eaxlerage of a great many unrelated items of varying variability, VVT1ich should makes its efficacy subject to great doubt, even i.f? a fixed-variable breakdown is all that is needed for Cieacision-making purposes. The next section will consider titiis point further. Other Aspects of Cost Accounting: Beware of Oversimplification In a number of instances, a breakdown of overhead 8 Some definitions recommended in the literature in— crlJude: l. Shut—down costs of ”every cost that could not kDe? eliminated by boarding up the hose plant" (in Clem N. Kohl, 'What is Wrong With Most Profit and Loss Statements, " N.A.C.A. EglretinlxvuLSec. 1, (July 1, 1937), 1211. 2. Costs of getting ready to produce a certain ‘VYDlume of business or costs that the management cannot or will not vary on the basis of actual output, N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 23, "Direct Costing," pp. g_i_t_., 1087. definition of fixed many arbitrary classi— were found in In practice the applied C=roduction mix, a gigantic practical problem of defining, fiixed and variable cost components, and, finally, such an cnyerall averaging process to yield an average variable cost EDear unit that anyone should be extremely wary of the results. Shame of the same wariness should be present when individual EDxcoducts, classes of customers, branches, and even salesmen éaxre analyzed as to their profit—contribution. This is rueacessary in the case of the smaller segments of an enter- EDITiSe, since joint costs are ever—present, and there is ‘aflLways present in joint cost allocations a great deal of a rbitrariness . Furthermore, the contributive effect of individual Sfiagments of an enterprise cannot be measured in terms of a Simple fixed—variable cost separation. What is necessary is 51 comparison of costs and/or revenues over which control iJS exercised, or costs and/or revenues which are specifically 1Identifiable with an individual enterprise segment. Which- <3ver way this is done, fixed costs become identifiable with Segments of the enterprise. Control and variability are not at all synonomous, except perhaps at the lowest levels of the enterprise. At 222 ‘higher levels, those in charge have a great deal to do with Ebolicy decisions concerning commitments into the future out CDf which fixed costs arise. Therefore, if the contributive esffect of their work is to be analyzed, all costs (fixed c>r variable) over which they have control must be included. Ifiie same holds true in the case of a product line, for there Etre fixed costs that would not have to be incurred without ‘tlle product line. Special-purpose equipment and certain Stalaried personnel are outstanding examples of such costs. Perhaps the best argument for the short-run income Eitatement was that presented by Philip Kramer who said that iqts chief advantage is "the segregation of the effect on cxosts of management's long-range policy decisions from . Charrent operation decisions."43 Kramer's idea, like all 1ihe other ideas concerning a short-run income statement, Siounds reasonable until it is realized that a significant EDOrtion of the fixed costs in a business enterprise could f’ time, unrelated to production as such and therefore not a. Ebart of inventoriable costs. In other words, fixed costs ante: costs of getting ready to produce as opposed to variable CHDSSts which are costs of actually producing. Such a {ed Overhead Costs 150,000 150,000 150,000 dm inistrative and Selling F‘ Costs 50,000 50,000 50,000 cDr‘ecasted Production For Year 240,000 units Rate for Absorbing EPixed Overhead Costs 12 months X $150,000 . $1,800,000 : $7.50 240.000 units 240,000 per unit Ibid. , 504. 231 From these data the following income statements are developed. Note that sales, the rate of variability for variable expenses, fixed costs and efficiency are all held constant in order to emphasize the effects of fixed over- head absorption. The fixed overhead absorbed changes solely because production differs in each of the three months. (all figures in thousands) June gply August Sales $480 $480 $480 COSt of Sales $400 $400 $400 Add Under- -0- 400 (75) 325 37.5 437.5 absorbed Overhead GJi‘Cbss Profit on Sales $ 80 155 42.5 Adm inistrative and Selling Expenses 50 50 50 - Net Income 51.2.1. SEE-5: 3701—5) (Loss) Strange as it may seem, each of the three months pr‘Qduces a different income figure and in one month there i . S a net loss. How can all of this make sense when sales a rQ equal in all three months? (Mr. Harris' question). Mr - Harris and his followers believe that the statements d . . Oh 't make sense and are 1ncomprehens1ble to management. 1‘at is required is a complete overhaul of accounting theory 232 for the determination of income which recognizes fixed costs for what they are, that is, the costs of a period not allocable to product and therefore not allocable to inventories (their argument). The new treatment of the fixed element of overhead costs would then produce the following income statements for the same three months. (all figures in thousands) June July August Sales $480 $480 $480 Cost of Sales* _gg _2_5_0_ 250 Gross Margin $230 $230 $230 other Costs Administrative and Selling :30 50 50 EPigxed Overhead 150 __;§g 150 bleat: Income § 30 § 30 § 30 I \’°\7ariable costs of merchandise only) With this innovation Mr. Harris was quite satisfied. Iii-ES income statements were understandable in terms of having Sales and Net Income vary sympathetically. The erratic r6253ults produced by under—and overabsorbed burden were EEJLJiJninated and replaced by what Mr. Harris believed was a mQre sensible measure of operating results. Actually the ideas expressed by Mr. Harris were not rleiVV; Garcke and Fells said practically the same thing in 233 1E387fl6 Their comments, as quoted below, consider only sealling and administrative costs (establishment expenses) latrt they apparently would have treated factory overhead sstnilarly if it were fixed in nature. Garcke and Fells in ‘triis comment and most other parts of their book assumed 'tliat.factory overhead was variable in nature. The course adopted by most of the best manufacturing firms is to value . . . manufactured articles on hand at their cost of production, without any addition for profit, or for standing charges as distinguished from factory charges. The practice of including in the valuation of stock a percentage for establishment expenses or standing charges is one which cannot be too strongly condemned, if on no other ground than that a business really the reverse of profitable might, by the simple device of manufacturing and accumulating a large stock, be made to appear for a time as at any rate self-supporting. 6Even though Garcke and Fells made comments similar to L43: - Harris', their objective was much different. Mr. Harris “75153; interested in income measurement while Garcke and Fells wGal-‘e interested in price determination via marginal costs. Gris~31.‘cke and Fells merely accepted for income measurement pur- C)Ses a figure that they intended to use as a price :iea'tLermining cost. For a complete explanation of Garcke and I35331.l's view, see Chapter Two on the “Influence of Price Eatlermination on the Content of Overhead", pp. 22-6. 7 . I) See Chapter Two on the “Influence of Price eat:ermination on the Content of Overhead", pp.24-6. 8Emile Garcke and J. M. Fells, Factory Accounts, IREJurth edition (London: Crosby Lockwood and Son, 1887), l2l-2. 234 At first glance this may not seem to be the same idea as that held by Mr. Harris. The identity is recognized when one realizes that when fixed costs are allocated to inventory and when inventories are increased, the propor- tion of a particular period's fixed costs included in inventory rather than cost of goods sold increases as the inventoriable stock increases. This is the same point Mr. Harris made when he wrote: . .desire for an understandable profit and loss statement was not unreasonable if one is willing to grant that a manufacturing company cannot realize a profit until its products have been sold. It cannot make money merely by producing goods for inventory. John Maurice Clark recognized the same principle in the early 1920's when he wrote, Making goods to stock increases the showing of net income available for dividends by just the amount by which the book cost of the goods ex- ceeds the differential cost. Professor Clark stated the same ideas in terms closer to Mr. Harris's when he said that the natural conclusion to the statement that "business is worth taking at anything more than its differential costs“ is that nothing but 9 Harris, pp. cit., 510. 10John Maurice Clark, The Economics 9; Overhead Costs (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1923), 241. 235 differential costs should be charged to product.11 He also said if an accountant would isolate constant costs from all others, he would have neither cost of production nor of idleness, but of readiness to produce, regardless of whether there is any production or not.12 As will be seen later these same ideas-concerning direct costing were at least implied in break-even analysis and the economist's graphic analysis of total costs and revenues which are products of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Direct Costing: The Period of Refinement Early Emphasis: Eliminate the Normal Overhead Concepp The early years of direct costing, that is, the period from the time of Mr. Harris's article (1936) through the early 1950's, saw the proponents utilizing some variation of Harris's illustration. A statement of their case (as it looked to opponents) was very well summarized as follows: A favorite illustration of theirs was to present two income statements, each with the same volume of sales but with final profit figures 11. , ibig., 251. 12 Ibid. 236’ quite different, or two income statements in which the one with the larger sales volume yields the lower profit figure. In both cases, management, usually the president, is represented as asking how such results are possible. The accountant . . . blames the results all on unabsorbed burden. Management is then assumed to become naively confused by this explanation being pictured as knowing little about the effects of low volume and high unit costs. The sequel to this state of affairs is that the accountant redesigns his records so as to do away with the ' baffling results of such statements. The new system, which inevitably must be direct costing, eliminates the apparently contradictory profit reporting by treating fixed costs (the villain) as period costs. The possibilities of over or under absorbed burden are avoided by the new concept of . l4 income measurement. The attack on the conventional system of reporting income seems to have been something of an evasive tactic, in that the new concept of income measurement was developed primarily to avoid estimating a normal or expected volume of production which could be used as the basis for overhead 13 ‘ George W. Frank, "Will Direct Costing Theory Stand Inspection?" N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXIV, Sec. 1. (December, 1952), 492. l4Ibid. 237 absorption. Over and over again in the literature a major point of the proponents of direct costing was that there would be no necessity to estimate normal or expected volume since all fixed costs would be excluded from inventory. Eliminating the necessity to estimate normal or expected volume was one of Mr. Harris's major points which he 15 followers eagerly adopted. The rather awkward emphasis on eliminating over—and underabsorbed overhead by means of eliminating the necessity to allocate fixed costs to inventory led Professor Doyle to make the following humorous, but quite appropriate, parody on Antony's speech to the mob (cost accountants everywhere) at the funeral of conventional cost accounting. Romans, country men, and lovers! hear me for my cause. If there be in this assembly, any dead friend of overhead costs, to him I say that direct costing's love of overhead was no less than his. If, then, that friend demand why direct costing rose against overhead allocation, this is my answer-—Not that we loved overhead allocation less, but that we loved our sanity more. Had you rather that overhead allocation were living and go nuts explaining it, than that overhead allocation were dead and ye can keep your marbles and sleep at night? 15Harris, pp. cit., 508-9. Leonard A. Doyle, "Overhead Accounting Comes Full Circle." N.A.C.A. Bulletin, xxv, (August, 1954), 1584. 238 Switch in Emphasis: Approach of the Economic Marginalist From a stress on avoiding calculation of normal out- putg there was a discernible change to a breakdown of costs into fixed and variable elements, as before, but with the (anphasis now on the view that fixed costs are costs of a period, costs of getting ready to produce, costs which will exiSt without actual production. The change in stress, although one author emphasized the period approach as early as 1937,17 was apparently the result of wide publicity given to the controversy here and abroad, which attracted the attention of many people familiar with economic marginalism and break—even analysis. Perhaps the most sophisticated publication emphasizing the period cost approach was that of the Englishmen, Lawrence and Humphreys, published in 1947 under the title Marginal Costing.18 The reason for the title becomes clear when it is realized that the authors' approach is an ex- tension of the economic theory of the firm dealing with price 17 Clem N. Kohl, “What is Wrong with Most Profit and LOSS Statements,"u.a.c.A. __B_ulletin, XVIII, Sec. 1. (July 1, 1937), 1217. 18 F C Lawrence and E. N. Humphreys, Marginal Costing (London: MacDonald and Evans, 1947), 117 pp. 239 and output decisions. The arguments presented can be summarized by saying that the income derived from a particu- lar sale is the difference between the sale price and the Inarginal cost of the item sold. To derive total income, all that is necessary is to take the sum of the incomes from all of the sales. To derive net income deduct the fixed costs for the period from the previously calculated total which is often called marginal income or the total contri- bution to fixed costs.l.9 There is no doubt that this argument has a telling effect on a great majority of those- who are willing to listen, especially those who are schooled in the rudiments of economic theory. In England the title marginal costing still prevails for the practice known as direct costing in the United States. Switch in Emphasis: Approach of the Break-even Enthusiast A variation of the marginal costing point of view is break-even analysis. The argument runs as follows: Under break-even analysis no profit is earned until fixed costs are covered--how then can fixed expenses be allocated to products? Fixed expenses are time expenses, not performance 19ibid., H | 13. 240 expenses, and should therefore be charged to the period in question, irrespective of production during that period. "This is the reasoning which supports the break-even formula."20 Switch in Emphasis: The Perfect Argument The almost perfect extension of the break-even argument took the form of a challenge to unbelievers.21 So refined was the approach, that it pinpoints the elements of the controversy. Illustrative of this approach is the following example of an assumed chemical fertilizer manu- facturer. 1958 Sales 10,000 tons @$ 20.00 per ton Production 15,000 tons Variable Costs $ 8.00 per ton Fixed Costs $150,000 According to the break-even formula the break-even point would be derived as follows: 20Alexander Bac, "Advantages of 'Break-even' Income Statement Compared With Conventional Statement," The Journal pf Accountancy,XCI (January,l95l), 109. 21Raymond P. Marple, "Try This on Your Class Professor," The Accounting Review,XXXI (July,1956), 492-295. 241 Break-even Point = Sales = Variable Costs As A + Fixed Percentage of Sales Costs S = V (S) +_F S a 8/20 (S) + $150,000 S = .4 S '+ $150,000 .68 = $150,000. S : $250,000 (12,500 Tons) According to conventional accounting, unit costs will be determined by dividing total costs by total pro— duction as follows: Total Cost + Total Production = Unit Cost Variable Costs.+ Fixed Costs ; 15,000 : Unit Cost 8 x 15,000 _+ 150,000 ; 15,000 2 Unit Cost 120,000 4. 150,000 ; 15,000 : $18.00 With a unit cost of $18.00 per ton and sales of 10,000 tons at $20.00 per ton, there is a profit of $2.00 per ton or $20,000.00. How can this be if the break—even point is 12,500 tons ($250,000)? Sales of less than the break—even amount should produce a loss, not a profit. The logical resolution of this dilemma, according to those who propose it, is that the break-even calculations are correct and accounting is all wrong. Accounting is "wrong" since it spreads fixed costs over all production, thereby including some fixed costs in inventory. 242 In the determination of periodic profit, the only costs which should be deferred in inventory for application against the future are those costs which, because they have been incurred in the past, will not have to be incurred in the future.22 ‘ The costs which will not have to be incurred in the future are the variable costs. The fixed costs are with us, with or without production. Following this approach to solving the dilemma, the results of operations for the year 1958 in the previous illustration should be as follows: Sales (10,000 tons @ $20 per ton) $200,000 Less Costs Variable $ 80,000 Fixed- 150,000 230,000 Net Loss _§(30L000) This loss of $30,000 is quite consistent with a break—even point of $250,000 for the added $50,000 of sales would result in a contribution of $30,000 to cover fixed costs, since $20,000 is necessary to cover the added variable cost element of added sales. The variable costs ($80,000) in the above very summarized income statement are the variable costs applicable to merchandise produced and sold (10,000 tons @ $8 per ton). Variable costs applicable to merchandise produced and not 221bid. , 497. 243 sold (an increase in inventories) are considered to be the total cost applicable to the inventory increase ($40,000 or 5,000 tons @ $8 per ton). Fixed costs ($150,000) are considered to be the costs of the period in which they are incurred and therefore they are not allocable to inventories. Traditional break-even analysis assumes sales and production equality. An inequality as presented here (sales 10,000 tons, production 15,000 tons) actually brings forth the conflict between conventional income measurement and break-even analysis. This conflict will be considered further in the next section of this chapter. The Case of the Defense 2911621531 One of the surprising features of practically all the literature on direct costing is the lack of con- sideration given to the recognition of loss from idle capacity. Garcke and Fells23 can be excused in this regard since these concepts were developed after their time. Mr. Harris24 and most of his followers apparently have no 23See "Direct Costing--Originsr pp. 232-4. 4 Jonathan N. Harris, pp. cit. 244 excuse, since, as shown in Chapter Two, the problem of idle capacity was given considerable attention by H. L. Gantt, Alexander Hamilton Church, G. Charter Harrison and many others. Furthermore, it is incredible to believe that Mr. Harris and his followers could have had no knowledge of these concepts because the National Association of Cost Accountants, an organization in which Mr. Harris was active, had considered these issues in its Bulletin25 and at its annual meetings as late as 1931.26 25Illustrative examples of the then available litera- ture are : A. F. Stock and J. M. Coffey, "Overhead During Low Volume Production," N.A.C.A. Bulletin. VI. Sec. 1 February 16, 1925), 11 pp. and Wyman P. Fiske, "Accounting for Unused Facilities," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XIII, Sec. 1. (November 15, 1931), 355-69. Illustrative presentations at annual meetings in— clude the following: William H. Alden, "Handling the Expense of Idle Time," National Association pf Cost Accountants'Yearbook, 1924 , 115- 20. ' Edward P. Rush, "In Establishing The Budget for Burden, Shall Normal Capacity Be Set To Allow Only For Operating Interruptions, Thus Giving A Normal Which Is The Maximum Just Possible of Attainment; Or Shall It Allow For Unused Capacity Due to Insufficient Sales Demand, Thus Giving a Maximum Which May PrObably Be Obtained," National Association p: Cost Accountants'Yearbook 1930, 167—71. Charles Reitell, "The Standard Cost Plan for the Naca Company," National Association pf Cost Accountants Yearbook, 1931, 14-15. Discussion, "Some Debatable Points in Cost Accounting Theory," National Association p; Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1924 Egg 1925, 229-72 and 157-205. 245 (Mr. Harris published his article in 1936 in the gygppygp ‘Bpllppip). All of this material was available to Mr. Harris as well as to all of his followers, since the concepts then known have become a standard part of the literature on cost accounting. In addition to the lack of consideration given to idle capacity, there was an equal lack of evaluation of the nature, intent, and purposes of economic marginalism and break-even analysis. Too many ideas concerning fixed costs, income measurement, economic marginalism, and break— even analysis were treated as if they were related and consistent with each other. Actually, many of the ideas adopted by direct costing advocates are not at all related to income measurement. As shown in Chapter One (Part IV "Income Measurement and the History of Overhead Costing") even traditional accounting concepts of income measurement include some ideas not at all related to income measurement. Unfortunately those who defended traditional accounting based their defense on the inadequacies of direct costing. In this chapter (under "An Improved Approach”) both the inadequacies of direct costing and traditional accounting will be considered. The inadequacies of both sides must be considered for (as will be shown) direct costing arose 246 out.of the inadequacies of traditional accounting. Idle Capacity as a Defense The idle capacity concept in accounting is an adaptation of the concepts of “economic waste” or "pool of ‘waste" described in Chapters Three and Four. As stated in 'both chapters the problem is one of recognizing the essential difference between utilized and unutilized capacity or fixed costs. As one accountant said many years ago, ”the expense chargeable against the shop should be only that portion of the constant expense which the current activity is of the normal activity, plus the actual variable ex- pense." The ratio of actual to normal output then determines the amount of fixed costs which can be included in inventory, and the difference between this amount and the actual fixed charges is designated as a loss, chargeable to management,28 because the facilities represented by these cOsts were sterile or non-productive. 7 Nicholas Thiel Ficker, Industrial Cost-Finding, Factory Management Course, Volume 5, (New York: Industrial Extension Institute, Inc., 1917), 477. 281bid., 475-78. 247 One of the best analyses of this part of the direct costing controversy was published in 1945 by Professor Charles Schlatter.29 He said that the utilized portion of fixed expenses or expenses of getting ready to produce are costs of production because there could be no production without such costs. To him, as to Mr. Noyes,3O it was simply a matter of economic causation. The problem of sales and income varying sympathetically is dismissed by means of the idea of unutilized fixed costs being considered losses which do not have an effect on Operating income. Operating income in conjunction with a specially designated "Fixed Manufacturing Expense Lost Through Non-Use” is used as a true measure of the firms‘ total progress. The "loss through non-use" suggests possible "greater earnings if the plant were not overequipped or if the volume of sales could be increased to require greater use of the facilities of pro- duction with which it is equipped."31 29Charles F. Schlatter, "Fixed Expensefl' The Accounting Review,XX (April,l945), 156-163. 30 . C. Reinhold Noyes, "Certain Problems in the Empirical Study of Costs,” The American Economic Review XXXI (Sept.,l94l), 482-86. 1 Schlatter, pp. cit., 161. Professor Schlatter's ideas can be illustrated by the following hypothetical income statements comparing his method and the direct costing method of handling fixed expenses. Schlatter's Method , 1957 Sales $175,000 Cost of Sales ' ' 125,000 Gross Profit on Sales $_50,000 Selling and AdministratiVe 25,000 Expenses Net Operating Income $ 25,000 Fixed Manufacturing Expense Lost Through Non—use 25,000 Net Income § 0 Direct Costing Method Sales Cost of Sales (Variable Costs Only) Gross Profit on Sales Sales and Administrative Expenses Net Operating Income Fixed Factory Expenses Net Income In 1957 sales and production are equal. 1957 $175,000 100,000 $ 75,000 25,099 $ 50,000 50,000 .i======2 1958 $175,000 125,000 $ 50,000 25,000 $ 25,000. __2—.<1..9.9.Q § 5,000 1958 $175,000 _l00,000 $ 75,000 25,000 $ 50,000 _m50,000 .§._.___Q Under the direct costing method the fixed expenses for the period (1957) are treated as one category, viz.; EXpense". expenses are divided into two categories, "Fixed Factory Under Schlatter's method fixed manufacturing "Cost of 249 Goods Sold" ($25,000) and ”Fixed Manufacturing Expenses Lost Through Non—Use" ($25,000). Under Schlatter's method actual output (sales and production equal) is one-half of practical capacity; this is the reason for considering one— half of the fixed costs as lost through non—use and the other half as part of the cost of producing the merchandise sold. In 1958 production is more than sales, which thereby increaSes inventory. The inequality of sales and production does not affect the direct costing statement, since cost of sales includes only the variable costs of goods sold and all fixed costs are considered costs of a period and not allocable to production. Thus, under direct costing, the costs allocable to the inventory accretion are the variable costs of production. Fixed costs are not considered costs of production under direct costing and therefore they are not considered part of inventories valued at cost; Under Schlatter's method the income statement is affected by the inequality of sales and production. Schlatter considers utilized fixed costs as costs of production and allocates utilized fixed costs to inventory. Thus,in 1958 when production is greater than sales, not as many fixed costs are considered lost through non-use as in 1957 when sales 250 and production were equal. The decrease in lost fixed costs ($5,000) is considered part of inventory costs, since these fixed costs were utilized in obtaining the inventory accretion. In the direct costing statement, there is sympathy between sales and net income, the goal of Jonathan N. 32 Harris, but in obtaining this sympathy Mr. Schlatter would have said that he (Harris) lost much more than he (gained, if he gained anything at all. Harris lost sight of the simple commen-gaug fact that all sacrifices incurred in connection with the manufacturing processes (including only the utilized element of fixed costs) should be associated with the results of such processes. The results are products and the sacrifices are the cost elements; thus the utilized fixed manufacturing expenses should be con- sidered costs of production. Goods manufactured and sold should be included in cost of goods sold at a cost price, including the proper portion of utilized fixed overhead costs. Goods manufactured and not sold should be included in inventory at a cost price, including the proper portion of utilized fixed overhead costs. Unutilized fixed over- head costs should be treated as a "loss through non-use". 32Supra, Footnote 5. 1 (I! III..||’|‘ (.1), 1.1‘ A J/ ‘1‘. l 251 Professor Schlatter showed clearly how Mr. Harris's problem concerning fixed manufacturing expenses could be handled. He (Schlatter) believed that the place where sympathy between sales and income could exist, assuming all other factors are held constant, would be at the "Net Operating Income" level of the income statement. Below the "Net Operating Income” level, there could be an unsympathetic relationship between sales and income due to the factor of unutilized fixed overhead costs. In addition, Professor Schlatter believed that he showed clearly the effect of wasted or unutilized capacity. Finally, the gravity of the contention that profits could be influenced by inventory manipulations33 is considerably reduced, since "Net Operating Income" is used as the measure of operating performance. Inventory changes would affect only the fixed costs lost through non-use which are shown below "Net Operating Income". An inventory increase would involve only a transfer from unutilized fixed costs to inventory. Schlatter believed that the transfer from unutilized fixed costs to inventory was an appropriate transfer because 33This is the problem considered by Garcke and Fells (Supra-Footnote 7), Jonathan N. Harris (gupra-Footnote 8). and John Maurice Clark (Supra-Footnote 9). 252 the previously unutilized fixed costs had been utilized in the processes of production due to the inventory increase. In the previous illustration of Schlatter's method, un- utilized fixed manufacturing overhead costs were $25,000 in 1957 and $20,000 in 1958. The difference is accounted for solely by the fact that production for 1958 was greater than sales to such an extent that $5000 of fixed manufacturing expenses were considered to be utilized and thus inventoried. The problem that remains with regard to utilized and unutilized capacity is the measure of total, or full, or 34 Ficker referred normal capacity. In the previous citation to normal capacity while Professor Schlatter refers to full practical capacity.35 The measure of capacity which is utilized can easily affect the dollar segregation between utilized and unutilized capacity costs. Through the years accountants, in attempting to quantify the capacity problem, have come up with a number of capacity definitions, most of which have been considered in Chapter Two. To a large extent the usual definitions can be regarded as platitudes, because some vague conception 4 Supra. Footnote 29. 35Schlatter, pp. cit., 160. 253 , _ , , 3 of normal capac1ty is ordinarily used. There is no quarrel here with the concepts of utilized and unutilized capacity. The solution put forth by Schlatter and most others is defective in terms of how to quantify the waste incident to capacity costs for income measurement purposes. These issues will be discussed further in succeeding pages. Recognizing Limitations of Marginalism Dealing with the marginal and break-even approach to direct costing is a problem that must be faced squarely. The refined direct costing approach which deals with break— even analysis presents more of a problem than the earlier burden absorption problems. Usually the defenders of con- ventional cost accounting bring forth such ideas as, the equality of production and sales assumed by marginalism and break-even analysis, and the aforementioned distinction 37 between utilized and unutilized capacity costs. 36599; chapter Two on normal capacity. PP- 71-4. 37See: R. Lee Brummet, "Try this On Your Class Professor--A Rejoinderfl The Accounting Review,XXXII (July,l957), 480-4. 254 If sales and production are equal there is no change in inventory, and if the fixed cost element assigned to product is the same in the equal physical inventories at both ends of the year, there is no_problem concerning income measurement. If, as is usually the case, there is a difference between production and sales, there will be a difference between the ordinary break-even measures and the accounting measures of income. At least two attempts have been made to overcome the failure of marginalism and break—even analysis to treat possible idle capacity and to overcome the assumption of production and sales equality. One attempt was inadequate in that the only solution offered was a calculation designed to determine the difference between the total fixed cost element in the beginning and ending inventory which was utilized to adjust the income figure determined by break- even analysis.38 Assuming the income per break-even calculations is $130,000, which assumes that all fixed costs are period costs, the income from the usual accounting point of View would be $130,000 plus or minus the difference 38 Wyman P. Fiske, and John A. Beckett, Industrial Accountant's Handbook (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1954), 63-64. 255 between the total fixed cost element in the beginning and ending inventories. For example, if the total fixed costs in beginning inventory were $4000 and in the ending inven- tory $10,000, the $6000 increase would be added to $130,000, since the conventional break-even analysis charges all fixed costs to the period, while accounting income measure— ment demands in this instance that $6000 of fixed costs belong in inventory which should thereby reduce expenses and increase income by $6000. The reverse would hold true if the total fixed cost element in inventories decreased. The other attempt involved the capacity concept and sales and production inequality in diagramatic exposition. In this case Professor Brummet completely discarded the old break-even diagram and replaced it with a diagram that would include the effects of wasted or unutilized capacity.39 The diagram is the logical diagrammatic exposition of the concept of wasted capacity. It uses what are known as 150- profit lines, that is, lines of~constant profit or loss or lines connecting all combinations of sales and production, that would produce the same income or loss. Sales and 39 R. Lee Brummet, Overhead Costing, Michigan Business Studies, XIII, No. 2 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan, 1957), 83-100. 256 production are utilized as the determinants of income rather than sales being the sole determinant, as is assumed in marginalism and break—even analysis. Sales has its effect on income by providing the revenues to absorb cost. Production has its effect on income in terms of whether or not all fixed production costs have been utilized. In this way sales provide revenues and production can provide a special form of waste, that is, un- utilized capacity. Income becomes bifunctional, that is, a function of sales and production (idle capacity), rather than monofunctional, that is, a function of sales. Under these circumstances a break—even point can be obtained by a number of different combinations of sales and production (idle capacity). Income produced by high sales could be offset by the idle capacity of lower production. A lower income produced by less sales could be offset by less idle capacity of a slightly higher production. On the other hand, a higher income produced by greater sales could be offset by the greater idle capacity of lower production. What holds true for a break-even position would also hold true for various levels of profit and loss. That is, each level of profit or loss could be attained by various combinations of sales and production (idle capacity) The diagramtredioilhBUEHa 257 this bifunctional or three dimensional approach is shown below: Illustration 3 Three Dimensional Break—Even Chart 1 Units of Sales ‘ $20,000 profit $10,000 Profit Break-Even $10,000 Loss 9 r 0 Units of Production As in traditional break—even analysis, constancy is assumed for prices of inputs and outputs. Efficiency is also assumed to be constant. The $10,000 loss line represents all those combinations of sales and production 258 (idle capacity) which result in a $10,000 loss. Large sales (more revenue) are combined with low production (more idle capacity) at one extreme while low sales (less revenue) are combined with high production (less idle capacity) at the other extreme. The same is true of a break-even position or any profit position. As it should be, the break-even position is above and to the right of the $10,000 loss position, that is, at higher sales (more revenues) and higher production (less idle capacity). The same is true of the successive levels of profit above the break—even position. Both of the above changes in traditional break-even analysis are attempts to support traditional accounting theory in the face of the proponents of direct costing. They represent adaptations of break—even analysis which are necessary to overcome limitations in a method which assumes sales and production equality and ignores unutilized capacity. Brummet's ideas, especially, present a rather 40 Brummet presents these same ideas in a two-chart ,system: one for recognition of the sales function and another for the recognition of the production function (wasted capacity). In addition he ties this two chart system into one chart which is slightly different from the one above. See Brummet, pp. pip., pp. 91-95. 259 formidable defense against the direct costing ideology which assumes that income is monofunctional, that is, a function of sales. In order to improve the defense and perhaps make it impregnable, it is necessary to introduce a few new ideas in addition to a recognition of old ideas for what they are. In this and in this way only is it possible to obtain agreement among accountants, and perhaps even between marginalists, break-even enthusiasts, and accountants. An Improved Approach General At the present time there are three basic assumptions involved in the accounting for overhead costs. These assumptions are: 1) a fixed-variable cost segregation is best for income measurement. 2) all fixed costs are related to long-lived asset acquisitions (fixed assets). 3) unit costs should not be allowed to vary with volume. The fixed-variable cost separation is admitted to be a difficult process, but as usual, all that is asked of practitioners is to do the best that can be done in a 260 difficult situation. Once the cost elements are separated into fixed and variable components, each group (fixed and variable) can be allocated to production on appropriate bases, e. g., variable costs on the basis of actual service and fixed costs on the basis of readiness to serve. The readiness to serve allocation method for fixed costs is used in all three capacity measures (practica1,norma1 and cycle capacity). Under each capacity measure variable overhead costs would be allocated to products on the basis of actual output. Presumably each unit of output is charged with those elements of variable overhead which it (the unit of output) gave rise to. A11 variable overhead would thus be allocated to output, for without output there would be no variable overhead costs. Under each capacity measure fixed overhead allocated to production is represented by the portion of capacity utilized multiplied by the fixed costs. The method of capacity measurement affects the measure of utilized capacity costs. Fixed cost allocation under the three—capacity measures can be illustrated by the following diagram: Capa ity Utilized 261 Fixed Measure of Overhead capacity Costs The meaning of "measure of capacity" for each of the three-capacity concepts would be as follows: CAPACITY CONCEPT Practical Normal Cycle MEASURE OF CAPACITY Physical output potential Average cyclical sales expectations Average cyclical sales expectations Capacity utilized would be actual output under all capacity concepts, and unutilized capacity under each of the three capacity concepts would represent the following: CAPACITY CONCEPT Practical Normal MEANING OF UNUTILIZED CAPACITY Idle capacity in a strict physical sense Idle capacity due to less than average use of fixed costs. 262 (cont'd) Cycle Deferred fixed costs to be utilized in the future when greater than average use of fixed costs occurs. Under normal and cycle capacity actual output can be greater than average cyclical sales expectations. Thus the 41 previous illustration would have to be changed as follows: i ' ’l' Overutilized CapaCity Actual Output Fixed Average Overhead Cyclical Sales Costs EXPGCt tlohs v Overutilized capacity would represent a special gain due to greater—than-average use of fixed costs under normal capacity, and a deferred credit due to greater-than-average use of fixed costs under cycle capacity. The deferred charges and deferred credits associated with the cycle 41In Chapter Two under "Summary: The Sequel to the Supplementary Rate" (pp.108-110) more detailed illustrations of the three capacity concepts are shown. 263 capacity concept are treated as offsetting items. Over- utilized capacity cannot exist under the practical capacity concept, since practical capacity is defined as physical output potential which cannot be exceeded. The above illustrations of capacity concepts and the treatment of overhead costs show how overhead costs are divided and allocated for income measurement purposes. Fixed overhead costs are assumed to be one lump sum which is cut into slices of equal cost for allocation to individual units. Each unit of actual output under all the capacity concepts has an equal fixed cost allocation.42 Thus, unit costs are not allowed to fluctuate with volume, that is, the fixed costs of a period are not allowed to be allocated to the actual output of the same period, and thus yield a varying fixed cost per unit based solely on changes in production volume. The possibility of unit costs fluctuating with volume is eliminated by means of the special treatment 'of unutilized and overutilized fixed overhead costs. Thus far, the assumptions concerning the fixed—variable cost breakdown and constancy of fixed overhead cost per unit have been illustrated. Both assumptions are inherent in all 42 Each unit of output also has an equal variable cost allocation. 264 three capacity concepts. The third assumption, which is also inherent in all three capacity concepts, is much more subtle and implicit. In fact it would probably be almost impossible to find an explicit statement that would admit that fixed overhead costs as used for income measurement are assumed to relate solely to long-lived asset acquisitions or fixed assets. The average cyclical sales expectations of normal and cycle capacity implicitly recognize the assumption of fixed costs applicable to long-lived assets, for the objective of normal and cycle capacity is presumably to average the fixed costs over the period to which they are applicable—~a cycle of years. Practical capacity also _implicitly assumes that fixed costs are all applicable to long-lived assets, since it measures capacity and allocates all fixed overhead costs on the basis of the physical attainable capacity of equipment. Objection is necessary to all three of the above expressed assumptions involved in the accounting for manufacturing overhead costs. A fixed-variable cost breakdown is not best for income measurement. All fixed costs are not and should not be related to long—lived asset acquisitions. Unit costs should be allowed to vary with volume under the conditions to be spelled out in succeeding 265 pages. Overhead Cost Segregation for Income Measurement For income measurement purposes overhead costs should not be segregated into the familiar fixed-variable dichotomy. A threefold categorization of manufacturing overhead would be best to illustrate the recommended approach to income measurement. The segregation is as follows: 1) Acquisition costs of long—lived assets (fixed assets). 2) Indivisible cost inputs related to supervisory personnel, practically all of the costs of service departments, and practically all of the expenses flunrred.by the plant superintendent's office and the manufacturing vice—president's office. 3) All other overhead costs; these are primarily the the costs of operating equipment and facilities At first there may not seem to be too great a dis— tinction between the twofold and the threefold categorizations of overhead costs. Categories (1) and (2) of the new three- fold grouping can almost be described as a breakdown of the old fixed cost category, while category (3) can almost be described as the old variable cost category. However, category (2)--indivisible cost inputs-—consists of cost elements (usually called semi-fixed or semi—variable) 266 which are segregated into fixed and variable components for purposes of refining the usual fixed—variable cost break- down. In addition to the threefold cost categorization recommended, there is another very important difference (perhaps the most important) in the approach to income measurement to be recommended. Each of the three cost groups is to be allocated to production in a different manner. The acquisition costs of long-lived assets are to be allocated to production on a unit of production basis. In other words, depreciation pp ppp to be calculated on a straight-line basis; depreciation lg to be calculated on a unit of production basis. Under straight—line depreciation the useful life of fixed assets is calculated in terms of years. Under the unit of production method the useful life of fixed assets is calculated on the basis of expected output during the time the fixed asset is expected to be used. Indivisible cost inputs are to be allocated to actual output produced. Indivisible cost inputs are costs that come in chunks (semi-variable). It is absolutely necessary to incur these "chunks” in order to obtain any output within the range of output serviced by the indivisible cost inputs. 267 These “chunks“ are added when production reaches a certain level, and such "chunks" are absolutely necessary to all output possibilities starting from the point where the ”chunk" is first added and ending at the point where it is necessary to add another ”chunk". All classes of super- visory personnel are perfect examples of ”chunk costs” which are absolutely necessary for all output possibilities within a certain range. Since these indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary for production, they must all be considered costs or production no matter what output is within the range for which the "chunk costs" are absolutely necessary. On the basis of these indivisible cost inputs, unit costs can and must vary with volume. If costs are ab- solutely necessary for production, they cannot be considered other than true costs of production and thus allocable to units produced. A system of accounting which will not allow unit cost figures to fluctuate on the basis of pro- duction volume and indivisible cost inputs is inaccurate. Such an accounting system takes the indefensible position of describing an absolutely necessary cost element as waste. Describing an absolutely necessary cost element as waste is a natural concomitant of those cost systems which 268 will not allow unit costs to fluctuate with production volume. If the unit cost is stabilized at the top of the "chunk cost" output range (practical capacity), the cost per unit would be stabilized at its lowest possible level. If production is at any point in the output range below the top point, the justifiable increase in costs per unit would not be allowed. The justifiable unit cost increase would be removed from production costs and classified as waste due to unutilized facilities in a strict physical sense (practical capacity). If the unit cost is stabilized at an average of expected output within the "chunk cost" output range (normal and cycle capacity), the cost per unit would be stabilized at the average unit cost level. If production is at any point above the average, the justifiable decrease in unit costs would not be allowed. The justifiable cost decrease would be removed from production costs and con- sidered as a special gain under normal capacity and a deferred credit under cycle capacity. If production is at any point below the average, a justifiable unit cost increase would not be allowed. The justifiable cost increase would be removed from production costs and considered as a loss due to less than average use of "chunk costs" under normal 269 capacity and a deferred cost due to less than average use of ”chunk costs" under cycle capacity. Thus, under any of the three capacity concepts an absolutely necessary cost of production could be considered as a loss due to unutilized capacity or as a deferred charge. Under normal and cycle capacity, when output is above average unit costs would be stabilized at an inflated level. The inflated unit costs would be offset by the bookkeeping manipulations of a special gain or a deferred credit due to greater than average use of "chunk costs". It seems hardly necessary to restate that unit costs should be allowed to fluctuate on the basis of whatever output is achieved within the range for Which ”chunk costs“ are absolutely necessary. None of the capacity concepts con- siders this possibility, and therefore all three concepts are in error. What are absolutely necessary costs of production cannot sensibly be considered otherwise. The third category of overhead costs is essentially variable in nature. These costs are incurred only if there is production, and thus they should be allocated to units produced. In the case of all three cost categories, costs are allocated to actual production, for it is actual production 270 which gives rise to these costs. Note that the actual production basis is usable for depreciation because depreciation is recognized on a unit of production basis. Actual production is usable for indivisible cost inputs because the indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary to produce actual output. Actual production is usable for the third cost category because of the variable nature of these costs. A possible objection to the use of actual production as the basis of allocating indivisible cost inputs is the case of retaining on the payroll supervisory employees even when they are not absolutely necessary for production. Such a case arises in times of recession where the salaries paid to excess supervisory personnel would be less than the costs of acquiring and training new supervisors when business conditions improved. Under these conditions there is no need to object; there is only a need to introduce a refine— ment into the treatment of indivisible cost inputs. If supervisory personnel are retained, not for present use but for expected future use, the costs of present retention should be allocated against the expected future use. Thus the costs of retention are not costs of production in the period in which they are paid; they are costs of production 271 of those periods in which we expect to gain benefit out of the present retention of supervisory personnel. Some might say that the problem of retaining supervisory personnel under depressed conditions is only an academic problem and really need not be considered. However, the academic nature of the problem is present only when business conditions are other than depressed. A graphic illustration of the traditional allocation of overhead costs and the method recommended here is pre- sented on the following page. lily I]: .Illll! I. 1'1!!! 272 Illustration 4 The Traditional and the Recommended Methods of Allocating Overhead Costs TRADITIONAL METHOD Allocate to Production on variable the basis of Overhead actual “COSt usage Allocate to production on the basis of the proportion of capacity utilized multiplied by fixed overhead costs RECOMMENDED METHOD Costs of Qperating Equipment and Depreciation Facilities Allocate on the basis of actual usage (output) Allocate on a unit of production basis (actual output) Indivisible Cost Inputs Allocate on the basis of actual output; the output for which in- divisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary. 273 In accordance with the ideas summarized in the pre— ceeding illustration, the old fixed—variable cost breakdown should be discarded for income measurement purposes. Fixed costs associated with straight-line depreciation should also be discarded in favor of depreciation on a unit of production or usage basis.43 ‘The fixed cost portion of indivisible cost inputs should be reassociated with their variable counter- parts, and then allocated to the output for which they were absolutely necessary elements of production. Finally, unit costs of production should be allowed to fluctuate with volume within the range for which indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary. Idle Capacity Costs and Income Measurement In general there should be no idle capacity costs for income measurement purposes due to a varying production volume brought on by changes in sales volume. The truth of this statement will be clear after a consideration of each of the cost categories recommended for purposes of income measurement. Depreciation of fixed assets should be on the basis 43 The practicality of a unit of production basis for depreciation will be considered in succeeding pages under ”Some Objections Considered". 274 of a useful life, for fixed assets are acquired to be used over a useful life. If the useful life expectancy turns out to be correct, all of the fixed asset costs will be allocated to the units produced.44 If the useful life expectancy is incorrect, all that is usually necessary is a change in depreciation rates as is ordinarily recommended in financial accounting. In the extreme case where a useful life is changed on account of unexpected technological change or market deterioration, an argument can be made for treating some of the fixed asset costs as a loss. Such a loss would be recognized at the time the change in expected life occurred. Useful life can be unexpectedly increased due to material increases in the market potential of present products, or development of new products which can be produced with present equipment. An unexpected increase in useful life is a kind of windfall which could possibly be treated as a gain in the accounting measurement of income. Between the extreme cases of change in useful life where an argument can be made for recognizing a gain or a A unit of output depreciation method is assumed to be utilized in this section unless otherwise stated. 1'11 I‘ll. I I'll I all. ll]! 1 275 loss, and the normal cases of change in useful life where depreciation rates are revised, there is a grey area where judgment must be exercised. Judgment comes into play when it is necessary to determine whether a particular case is an extreme wherein gain or loss could be recognized, or the more usual case involving a revision in depreciation rates. Thus, for fixed asset costs the only case that can be made for recognition of gain or loss due to volume considerations relates to the extreme cases of change in the useful life of a fixed asset. Since indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary for all output ranges which they service, none of the indivisible cost inputs can lead to a loss due strictly to a fluctuation in volume. Indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary for production within their relevant range, and therefore none of the indivisible cost inputs could be considered as a loss or waste. On occasion a case may arise in which indivisible cost inputs are retained when output dips below the point where such costs are necessary. This is the extreme case ‘where an employee may be kept on the payroll for one of two reasons. One reason is that costs of retaining an employee Inight be less than the costs of hiring and training a new 276 employee when business revived. The other reason is a matter of sentiment, where trusted and faithful employees are being rewarded for their prior services by being retained on the payroll when their services are not really necessary. In either of these two cases there is still no loss due to wasted capacity. The costs of retaining an employee for the future are costs applicable to the future; they are not losses of the period in which they are paid. The costs of retaining employees on the payroll for sentimental reasons can be considered as costs applicable to prior periods of service or as a distribution of psychic income to the owners of an enterprise. Thus in no case can indivisible ’cost inputs be considered losses due to fluctuations in the volume of production. The last category of overhead costs is the cost of operating equipment and facilities. There can be no 1055 here due to changes in production volume, for such costs are variable in nature. Decreases in production volume would decrease these variable costs, and increases in production costs would increase the variable costs. The increases or decreases are simply expressions of costs necessary for production. Overhead costs cannot be considered as elements of 277 waste due to changes in marketability of product which bring on changes in production volume. The only exception to this general statement would be an extreme case of change in product marketability or equipment obsolescence that would change the useful life of a fixed asset. Other changes in the useful life of fixed assets are handled not as losses or gains but as revisions in depreciation rates. Indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary production costs within their relevant ranges. Indivisible cost inputs retained when not needed for present output are not wastes; they are costs applicable to the future or to the past, or an expression of psychic income. Since variable inputs (the only other category of overhead) vary with volume, there is no waste in such costs due solely to changes in commercial conditions. A logical question at this point would be: If the above statements on the general inapplicability of idle capacity costs are correct, why have accountants accepted for so many years the possibility of idle capacity costs? An answer to this question is possible only if the rational foundations of each capacity concept (practical, normal, and cycle) are considered. Practical capacity is the outgrowth of the comparison 278 of actual output with physical output potential of facilities. The comparison is logical in its own right. It is primarily related to engineering comparisons that are and should always be made in industrial plants. The comparison stated in the form of a question would be: How much more output can be produced with existing facilities? A knowledge of the physical output potential of a plant as a whole as well as the physical output potential of individual departments or items of equipment is useful for scheduling activities and possible capital expenditure decisions. However, for purposes of income measurement it is the "useful life" of equipment, not the "physical output potential" (comparable to physical life), that is appropriate. The measurement of additional output possible with existing equipment is perhaps made best in terms of physical units of output. However, the measurement of "lost" or "unused" output potential in dollars could be useful for certain purposes. Management might be interested in a figure which tells how much total and unit cost could be removed from present output if expected output (useful life) could be increased to physical output potential (physical life). Economists might also be interested in a dollar figure 279 that would represent a measure of unutilized physical out- put potential. This dollar amount is the measure of economic waste (unutilized fixed costs from an economists' View) as developed in Chapter Three. Within the field of economics the concept of economic waste is part of the losses due to misallocation of resources. Losses due to resource mis— allocation are not related to income measurement; they are .only useful as evidence of the fact that economic activity, from the viewpoint of an aggregate economy, could have been directed more efficiently. The practical capacity concept can be said to produce a "loss", but the "loss” is not at all related to income measurement. The "loss“ is simply an expression of the total cost that could be removed from expected output (useful life) if expected output could be increased to physical output potential (physical life), or an expression of economic inefficiences that could be decreased or removed by a better allocation of resources (direction of economic activity). The grafting of the practical capacity concept onto accounting measurements of income is probably nothing more than the outgrowth of the influence of engineers on early industrial accounting. The normal capacity concept is the outgrowth of the 280 practical capacity concept and the search for a cost 45 A determining price and a measurement of efficiency. unit cost useful for long-range price determination should be based on an average expected use of facilities, and should not be allowed to fluctuate with fixed cost absorption. Fixed cost absorption has no effect on the value of mer- chandise, and thus it should not be allowed to affect unit costs. A unit cost figure which varied only with shop efficiency (not fixed cost absorption) would produce a fairly good overall measure of the extent and direction of efficiency. With an unvarying fixed cost per unit, the normal capacity concept produces over-and underabsorbed fixed costs. The under- and overabsorbed fixed costs are related to the difference between actual output and average expected output. The under- and overabsorbed fixed costs are con- sidered as losses and gains solely because those who advocated normal overhead were unable to divest themselves completely of an attachment to the practical capacity concept. Another possible reason why under- and overabsorbed fixed costs are considered as losses and gains is the refusal of 45 See Chapter Two especially ”The Ideas of H. L. Gantt" and "The Normal Overhead Concept", pp. 56-65 and pp. 66-76. 281 the accounting profession to recognize that the averaging of fixed costs over expected output should be followed through with a deferred charge and deferred credit treatment of under— and overabsorbed fixed overhead.46 As it is generally promulgated today, the normal overhead concept is related to a combination of a long—run price determining cost and the practical capacity concept' which demanded that underabsorbed fixed costs be treated as a loss. Since the practical capacity concept has already been shown to be inapplicable to income measurement, it is only necessary to state that what is good as a price indicator (and even an efficiency indicator) is not necessarily good for income measurement purposes. The advocates of the normal capacity concept have failed to recognize the inapplicability of their approach to income measurement, and out of the inapplicability of normal capacity arose the direct costing controversy.47 Fortunately, the early direct costers recognized the inapplicability of the normal overhead concept and its concomitant gains or 46 Brummet, pp. cit., 82. 47See the preceeding section of this chapter on "Direct Costing: The Period Of Refinement", pp. 235-37. 282 / losses due to over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead. Un- fortunately, however, the direct costers did not remove the inadequacies of normal overhead from accounting for income measurement. The direct costers only avoided the inadequacies of normal overhead by eliminating fixed overhead costs from . 48 . . . production costs. The defenders of traditional accounting for income measurement didn't even recognize the inadequacies of the normal overhead concept; all they did was to argue that fixed costs are costs of production via a practical . 49 . . . . capac1ty concept (this eliminated the embarraSSing over— 50 51 absorbed overhead) or a cycle concept. The cycle concept eliminated the gain and loss treatment of over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead and thus eliminated an un- sympathetic relation between sales and income. An unsympathetic relationship between sales and net income was 48Ibid. 4 9See Schlatter, lpp. cit. 0 Overabsorbed overhead is embarrassing because it is treated as a gain which is offset by an inflated unit cost figure. 1 Joseph Mauriello, "Convertibility of Direct and Conventional Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV,Sec. l. (March/1954), 893. 283 the keystone of the early direct costing argument.52 The cycle capacity concept is primarily the outgrowth of using a business cycle rather than a year as the basis for measuring periodic income.53 Fixed overhead is averaged over the years of the cycle and thus the cycle concept does not yield a gain or loss due to under-or overutilized 54 The lack of gains or losses due to volume facilities. changes is quite consistent with the approach an overhead accounting recommended in this dissertation, but the cycle capacity concept gains the favorable feature of no gains or losses due to volume changes at too great a cost. The error in the cycle concept is that it aims at leveling out the results of a year or series of years, so as to make the results of individual years uniform. The advocates of the cycle concept forget that the results of each year should be made to stand out prominently. The cycle concept evades the fact that indivisible cost inputs ("chunk costs") are entirely applicable to 52 See the preceeding section of this chapter on "Direct Costing ; Origins" pp.229—235 53 See Chapter Two on "The Cycle Overhead Concept", ppJ6-90. 54 Brummet (pp. cit., 71-2) recognizes the possibility of gains or losses on the basis of changes in average sales expected over the cycle. This is the same as a change in the useful life of a fixed asset. 284 whatever output they are used to produce. Thus considering the "chunk costs” of production, the economic fact of varying unit costs would be averaged into oblivion by the normal overhead concept. If one is interested in a cycle type of concept, let him add together the short period Velements of the cycle in order to obscure the ripples in economic activity for Whatever purpose he has in mind. For accounting\purposes of income measurement the economic facts of life cannot be ignored. The task is simply one of determining a unit cost figure on the basis of estimated output for a peridd and the costs necessary to produce such an output (including all of the "chunk costs"). These are the data concerning a particular operating period which do not obscure or normalize out of existence the economic individuality of different operating periods.55 The calculations of practical capacity are not appropriate for income measurement because they are based on "physical life" not "useful life". The calculations of normal capacity are not appropriate for income measure— ment because they are based primarily on a price determining 55 The normalization of net income under the cycle concept comes from the adoption of an unvarying fixed cost per unit which would average "chunk costs" over output expected in a cycle of years. 285 cost which is not necessarily appropriate for income measurement purposes. The calculations of cycle capacity arenot appropriate for income measurement because they average the economic individuality of different operating periods. Add to the above stated inadequacies of the various capacity concepts the erroneous assumptions implicit56 in E all capacity concepts, and we have the arguments necessary to discard all of the traditional concepts of allocating fixed overhead costs. In place of the traditional concepts the approach to income measurement recommended in this disser- tation would be substituted. Overhead costs would be classified as 1) acquisition costs of long—lived assets (fixed assetsL 2) indivisible cost inputs or "chunk costs". 3) all other overhead costs; these are primarily the costs to operate equipment and facilities. Depreciation would be allocated to production on a unit of production basis. Chunk costs would be allocated to actual 56 . 1) A fixed-variable cost segregation is best for income measurement. 2) All fixed costs are related to long-lived asset acquisitions (fixed assets). 3) Unit costs should not be allowed to vary with volume. 286 output, and all other overhead costs would also be allocated to actual output. Finally, there would be no recognition of loss or gain due merely to the fluctuations in production volume based on commercial conditions. Some Objections Considered It would seem that there are two possible objections to the method of accounting for overhead recommended in the preceeding pages. Objection one relates to the practicality of calculating depreciation on a unit of output basis. Objection two relates to the possibility of subjecting supervisory salaries to a unit of production cost amorti- zation plan. For those who claim that they utilize a normal d,57 there capacity concept for allocating fixed overhea should be no problem in calculating unit of production depreciation. The normal capacity concept yields a perfect approximation to unit of production depreciation if under— and overabsorbed straight-line depreciation is treated as an adjustment of the allowance for depreciation. There is no suggestion here that one should revert 57 The normal capacity concept is most often used in overhead accounting. See Chapter Two on "The Normal Overhead Concept". pp. 71-74. 287 to a normal or cycle overhead concept- All that is suggested is that the average cyclical sales expectation of normal and cycle capacity can yield an approximation to unit of output depreciation. The only costs that would be subject to the normal or cycle concept would be depreciation costs and possibly the taxes and insurance on depreciable property. The taxes and insurance on depreciable property are a part of the costs of utilizing equipment and thus they could justifiably be allocated to production on the same unit of output basis as depreciation costs. The dollar equivalence of the unit of production depreciation method and the normal or cycle approach to capacity accounting (as applied to depreciation and perhaps insurance and taxes on depreciable property) can be illustrated by the following examples concerning an item of equipment. Illustration 5 UNIT OF PRODUCTION DEPRECIATION Cost (less salvage) $ 3,000. Expected output 150,000. Depreciation per unit $02 :Xears Output" Depreciation Charged To Product 1 20,000 $ $400 2 25,000 500 3 30,000 600 4 35,000 700 5 40,000 800 150,000 5 3,000 288 Illustration 6 Depreciation Costs Under Normal or Cycle Capacity Cost (less salvage) $3000 Useful life 5 years Depreciation per year $ 600 Expected output during useful life 150,000 units Average expected output per year 30,000 units (150,000 ; 5 ) Ratio of Actual §traighp- Depreciatiqg Depreciation Actual Output to Averagp X Line Charged to (under) or thput Outogp pepreciation Egpduct Overabsorbed 20,000 20/30 , s 600 $ 400 $ (200) 25,000 25/30 600 500 (100) 30,000 30/30 600 600 -0— 35,000 35/30 600 700 100 40,000 40/30 600 800 200 150,000 3000 $3000 -0- — As shown in the above illustrations, the amount of depreciation charged to production is the same in each year under the unit of production method and the normal or cycle capacity method. The equivalence between the two methods could be made complete if under- and overabsorbed depreciation were regarded as deferred credits or deferred charges, or perhaps as adjustments to the allowance for depreciation. In any case the equivalence of unit of production depreciation and the cycle or normal capacity concept used for depreciation 289 would be present in the income statement as long as under- and overabsorbed straight-line depreciation is kept in the balance sheet. There can really be no complaint such as "It is too difficult to apply in practice the unit of production depreciation method,” for the most often used capacity concept would yield a perfect approximation to unit of production depreciation. Practitioners could retain straight- line depreciation and at the same time apply the already— used normal overhead concept to yield an approximation to unit of production depreciation. Today in many business enterprises manufacturing facilities are leased rather than purchased. Thus the question cones up concerning the allocation of lease rentals to output. Since the lease is only another way of acquiring the service utility of property, there should be no new problem here. A lease involves the acquisition of property with someone else's money, rather than with the purchaser's money as in the case of an outright purchase. The periodic payments on a lease can be regarded as regular installments paid for the total useful service potential of the property during the life of the lease. Thus the total lease payments can be added up, and divided by useful life in terms of 290' units of output in order to yield a unit of production method of cost allocation for the lease costs. The unit of production method is defensible in the case of a lease, since a lease still represents the acquisition of the expected output use of an asset during the life of the lease. An extension of the unit of output amortization plan for lease rentals, can possibly be made to supervisory salaries. Under an argument which states that supervisory salaries should be made subject to a unit of output amortization plan there is one implicit assumption, viz., salary payments are not given for services in the year or month paid, they are only periodic payments given as an installment on the total useful service potential of the supervisor.58 Such an assumption was accepted above for leasehold rentals, but there seems to be quite a bit of stretching necessary to use the same assumption for super- visory salaries. Supervisors are paid for whatever use- fulness they can render within the volume range they are 58 This is also an implicit assumption in the cycle overhead concept. The unreasonableness of the assumption is recognized when clerical and service department costs incurred by or for the factory are considered. Clerical and service department costs are "chunk costs" necessary for all volumes within the range of volumes they are capable of servicing. 291 necessary for. When the upper limit of a supervisor's volume range is reached another supervisor is added. When the lower limit of a supervisor's volume range is reached the supervisor may be dropped from the payroll, or kept on the payroll for future service, as recognition of reliable past service, or as a form of psychic income for management. When an unnecessary supervisor is retained, his wages should be charged to future (past) periods benefited or as a current consumption of income (psychic income for manage- ment). It is the opinion of the author that a unit of 59 is unacceptable for super- production amortization plan visory salaries for two reasons: 1) Supervisors are paid for whatever usefulness they can render within the volume range they are necessary for. 2) A unit of production amortizatiai plan would yield the undesirable effect of normalizing supervisory costs per unit of output, which would have a tendency to normalize income. The two possible objections (perhaps modifications) of the accounting for overhead costs recommended in this dissertation are not valid in the eyes of the author. A unit of production method of depreciation is not easy to quantify. All that is recommended is that practitioners 59The same would hold for the "cycle overhead plan" which could yield an approximation to the "unit of production plan". 292 either make the attempt to quantify the unit of production method or use an approximation thereto. The approximation would be the normal or cycle overhead concept applied to depreciation (insurance and taxes on depreciable property also). The normal overhead concept is the most extensively utilized overhead concept, and thus the approximation to the unit of production method for depreciation is calculable on a practical basis. Supervisory costs could not logically be considered as a form of lease rental, so supervisory costs must be considered with other "chunk costs" as the cost of producing whatever output is produced within the relevant volume range. The Misguided Marginalist and Break-Even Enthusiast In the preceeding pages (The Case of the Defense) idle capacity costs are used as a defense against the direct cost approach to income measurement. Idle capacity is now lost as a defense against the direct costing ideology, be- cause under the improved approach to overhead costing recommended here there can be no idle capacity costs.6O 60 The only exceptional case where idle capacity costs can exist relates to extreme changes in the useful life of fixed assets. 293 Thus the direct costing approach to income measurement must be discredited on other grounds. The most appropriate grounds on which to discredit direct costing are on the basis of the exact nature and intent of economic marginalism and break-even analysis. Economic marginalism is not related to the measurement of income; economic marginalism is only a method of illustrating income maximization via the determination of the most pro- fitable price and output combinatiai in the short—run. The only cost factors to consider in the short—run are variable costs, for they are the only cost elements of significance in short-run price and output determination. As stated by Noyes, marginalism is a means of concentrating attention on strategic factors, that is, the incremental factors in- cluding variable costs.61 The lack of consideration given to fixed costs by economic marginalism does not mean that fixed cost elements are not costs, it simply means that fixed costs have no relevance to short-run price and output decisions. The fact that fixed costs are costs of production and allocable to production is a point made by economists and others when they consider the problems of public utility rate-making 61Noyes, pp. cit., 485. “_— 294 and the rational foundations of the Robinson-Patman Act. In both of these cases the problem is one of allocating fixed charges to products or services. In the case of public utilities, equity demands a just apportionment of fixed expenses to the beneficiaries of the services. In the case of the Robinson-Patman Act the problem of the big buyer wielding the club of the large order is the issue. Incremental or marginal pricing is considered unjust since all buyers contribute to the effects of volume and therefore all should be subject to a just apportionment of fixed costs. Price differentials are considered a luxury which must be cost justified. In other words, fixed costs are costs of producing products or services. Anyone who considers economic marginalism an argument for direct costing completely misunderstands marginalism. Short-run price and output determination which concentrates on incremental costs and revenues is the object of marginalism; the measurement of income has nothing to do with marginalism. Break—even analysis is also unrelated to income measurement. The intent of break-even analysis is to focus attention on the strategic factors (incremental costs) involved in short-run decision-making. Short-run 295 decision-making related to income maximization is a far cry from income measurement which is a long-run concept. If break-even or marginal analysis is to be used as a means of measuring income, two very basic assumptions must be spelled out, viz.: 1) there is an equality of sales and production 2) production inefficiency is assumed to be constant or nonexistent Consideration of an inventory problem, that is, an inequality of sales and production, is almost impossible to find in the literature of marginal and break—even analysis. If (as is usual) there is an inequality in sales and pro- duction, modifications must be made in the break-even or marginal approach to income measurement. Only the fixed and variable costs applicable to sales must be shown in the break—even chart used to measure income. The fixed and variable costs applicable to inventory must be removed from the break-even calculations. Another possible modification producing the same effect, would be a calculation concerning 62A somewhat crude attempt is made to recognize this problem in C. E. Knoeppel and Edgar E. Seybold, Managing For Proflp (New York: McGraw Hill Book Co., Inc., 1937), 178. 296 the difference between fixed costs included in the beginning and ending inventories, which would be used to adjust the traditional break-even income calculation. If there are $6000 more of fixed costs in the ending inventory, $6000 would be added to the break—even income calculation, since the break-even income calculation included $6000 of fixed costs which were allocable to the ending inventory. If there are $6000 less of fixed costs in the ending inventory, $6000 would have to be deducted from the break-even income calculation, since the break-even calculation did not include $6000 of fixed costs applicable to the inventory reduction. Break-even and marginal analysis assume implicitly that income is monofunctional, that is, a function of sales. A monofunctional relationship was actually the goal of direct costing advocates, since they always sought a direct sympathy between sales and income. Professor Brummet's ideas on idle capacity as a form of waste yield a bi— functional income determination.63 Income is considered to be a function of sales and idle capacity by Brummet. Of course Brummet, like break-even analysis, assumes that 63 See "The Case of the Defense" in this chapter, pp.254-59, 297 Eiroduction inefficiency is constant or nonexistent. A realistic approach to income measurement is that it is (metermined by a multitude of functions including sales, syales mix, and the innumerable forms of waste and inefficiency vfliich are always present when human beings are present. Among the wastes which are an ever—present part of the production process are price and usage variances traditionally segregated from efficient costs under standard costing. In the case of overhead there would be waste due to improper use of fixed assets, indivisible cost inputs and the costs of operating equipment and facilities. Idle capacity costs are not considered as waste for income measurement for they relate to the "physical life" and not the "useful life" of assets and also the inappropriate practical and normal capacity concepts. The original goal of direct costing, that is, the elimination of the normal overhead concept, was admirable. The normal overhead concept was and still is entirely inappropriate for income measurement. Under- and overabsorbed overheads produced by the normal overhead concept were the combined results of a cost determining price and a throwback to the practical capacity concept (recognition of loss due to idle capacity). Neither the cost determining price nor 298 'the "physical lifeH feature of practical capacity have any necessary relation to the measurement of income. The cycle capacity concept did not save traditional accounting concepts from error by treating under— and overabsorbed overhead as deferred charges and deferred credits. The cycle concept merely concentrated the error of traditional accounting in the normalization of unit costs and income. Direct costing focused attention on an error in traditional accounting, but devices used to correct the error were entirely inappropriate, that is, elimination of normal overhead via a marginal or break—even approach to income measurement. The opponents of direct costing failed to recognize the error in traditional accounting and tried to defend the traditional accounting for overhead on the basis of the inappropriate practical and cycle capacity concepts. The proponents of direct costing failed to recognize that neither marginalism nor break-even analysis were methods of measuring income. Both proponents and opponents of direct costing failed to recognize the real inadequacies in the traditional accounting for overhead costs which were embodied in the assumptions underlying each of the three capacity concepts; viz.: 299 l) A fixed-variable cost segregation is best for income measurement. 29 All fixed costs are related to long—lived asset acquisitions (fixed assets). 3) Unit costs should not be allowed to vary with volume. Overhead costs should be classified for income measurement into three categories, viz.: 1) Costs related to fixed asset acquisitions including depreciation, and insurance and taxes on depreciable property. 2) Indivisible cost inputs ("chunk costs") 3) All other overhead costs which are essentially the costs to Operate equipment and facilities- Group (1) costs should be allocated on a unit of production basis, and groups (2) and (3) should be allocated to the actual output produced. The indivisible cost inputs (many times called semi-variable costs) can yield a varying cost per unit dependent on production volume within the range serviced by the indivisible cost inputs. A varying unit cost on the basis of indivisible cost inputs is quite sensible, for indivisible cost inputs are absolutely necessary costs of production for every volume possibility ' within the range they service. Income measurement in accounting is a process of matching sacrifices (costs) and the results of the sacrifices 300 (revenues). Costs would include all of the overhead costs necessary for production (the traditional fixed and variable costs are both included here). If goods remain on hand at the end of a period they should be valued at their cost of production (all overhead costs included) in order that the costs of items sold may be properly matched with the. revenues they create. Inventories are costs held in abeyance so that they may be properly matched or associated with the revenues created by the sale of the inventory in succeeding periods. A proper association of costs and revenues yields the measure of income which is sought after in accounting. If wastes or inefficiencies64 occur in the process of manufacture and they can be identified,65 they should be removed from inventoriable costs. Waste and inefficiencies represent losses or drains on the income generated in the period in which the wastes occur. Wastes and inefficiencies are consumers of income, not producers of income, and 64 . . Since idle capac1ty costs are generally non—existent for income measurement purposes, they would not be included in the wastes and inefficiencies used in income measurement. A cost due to misused capacity (technical rather than commercial efficiency) would logically be a part of income measurement. 65 The goal of standard costing is to identify waste. 301 therefore they cannot be accumulated in inventories. Inventories are the resting ground of all effective efforts to produce income. Wastes should be deducted from income in the period in which they occur, for they represent the difference between income as it should have been and income as it actually was. Summary Income measurement is a process of matching effort expended with benefits received. Effort expended must of necessity include fixed and variable costs of overhead, for neither of these efforts would have been expended unless there was some goal or benefit to be obtained. Any wastes or inefficiencies in the efforts expended should be identified at least in internally-used financial statements. The focusing of attention on such wasted effort in terms of presenting income as it should have been compared to what it actually was is no doubt the best means of indicating the total impact of waste to the dollar-minded executive. Such wastes consume income in the period in which they occur. They cannot in any sense be considered generators of income, and therefore should not be held in abeyance in the form of inventory, which is the resting place of all effective 302 efforts expended to produce income. When the income is realized, then the inventoried efforts associated therewith are removed from inventory and considered as costs of revenue production in order to set forth clearly the results of operations. Wastes include the misuse of all cost inputs, whether they be associated with materials, labor, or overhead. Idle capacity costs are not considered with these wastes, because for income measurement purposes there are no such things as idle capacity costs. The dilemna created by break—even and marginal analysis is not really a dilemma at all, for such analyses are not intended to measure income. They are intended to maximize income by means of pointing out the incremental aspects of cost and revenue necessary for decision—making. Any use of marginal or break—even analysis to measure income is a clear violation of intended purpose as well as a misrepresentation of fact. This point should be well recognized by those who have considered the problems of public utility rate—making as well as the rational foundations of the Robinson-Patman Act. To many the challenge to the accountant's method of determining income, presented by direct costing, has brought forth a more refined and defensible method of measuring income. This would be it:s preoccupation with aJuci the fixed-variable Accounting measures of " physical life" factor 303 true only if accounting disposed of the inapplicable capacity concepts segregation of overhead costs. income should not be subject to the in practical capacity, the sales price ixiexology of normal capacity, and the normalizing or averaging txaruflency of cycle capacity. Income can only be measured Mflieuu every attempt is made to segregate and allocate over— }Meaci costs properly to units of output so that costs of PIVDéhJcts may be matched or associated with the revenues <3elfiwxed from the sale of merchandise. CHAPTER VI THE MODERN APPROACH TO OVERHEAD COSTING AND COST CONTROL AND THE NEED FOR AN INTEGRATED AND CONTINUOUS APPROACH Traditional Cost Control There has truly been very little change in the approach to cost control since the time of John Whitmore. Whitmore wanted the costs of idle capacity to be shown as a dollar figure which was to be an income statement deduction. By highlighting the idle capacity loss as an income deduction, rather than allocating it to product on the basis of a supplementary rate, Whitmore believed management would be made to realize the true impact of the loss. Then manage- ment would institute the procedures necessary to analyze idle capacity costs by cause and responsibility in order that the waste might be eliminated.1 G. Charter Harrison and others took the same atti— tude towards cost control when standard costs came upon the 1See Chapter Two on "The Rising Influence of Cost Control: A. Hamilton Church and His Supplementary Rate," especially the section entitled "The Prime Critic: John Whitmore." pp. 48-51. 305 2 With standard costing, though, dollar industrial scene. variances were accumulated for wastes of materials and labor as well as overhead, but the approach was still the same, that is, to accumulate variations (wastes), then analyze them by cause and responsibility in order that effective procedures might be instituted to eliminate the detected wastes. In the case of overhead, recognition of the fact that the variance accumulations were summarizations of a multitude of unrelated items of varying variability and fixity led to the cOncepts of responsibility accounting and the related flexible or variable budgets.3 2For example see: G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting to Aid Pro— duction," Industrial Management,LVI-LVII (October,l918— June.l9l9), 273—82, 39l-8,456-63,131—9,218—24, 314—18, 400-4, 483-7. G. Charter Harrison, "Scientific Basis for Cost Accounting," Industrial Management,LIX (March, 1920), 237—42. George A. Prochazka, "Controlling Costs by Their Variations, ” Industrial Management LXXIII (January—March, 1927), lO— 15, 117—22, 147- 50. 3See Chapter Two on "Cost Control and the Development of Overhead Costing" and Chapter Four on ”Responsibility Accounting." pp.125-28 and 199-205. See also: Clarence B. Nickerson, "Cost Control——A Review of Techniques, " .AQA3Bulletin XXIX Sec. 1.(July 15, 1948), 1399- 1408. 306 Vfiith flexible budgets, costs are accumulated by responsibility centers, and individual cost elements are classified by Object of expenditure within each responsibility center. 'Variances are then accumulated for individual items of expense in each responsibility center by comparing budgeted and actual amounts. Still, the approach to cost control is the same, that is, to eliminate the waste after the variances are accumulated, which effectively means that the only cost control feature inherent in the accumulations is the elimination or reduction of similar wastes in the future. The approach to cost control thus far considered is the approach still accepted in most quarters. It is the approach discussed in most texts on industrial management 4 and :1st accounting. It is the approach that is inherent 4 For examples see: Richard N. Owens, Management 9; Industrial Enterprises (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., l955),d638-8 and 643. ‘ Franklin G. Moore, Manufacturing Management (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1953), 738 and 742. Ralph C. Davis, Industrial Organization and Management (New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1940), 598—622. L. P. Alford and Russel H. Beatty, Principles 9; Industrial Management, Rev. Ed. (New York: The Ronald Press Company, 1951), 591. Cecil Gillespie, Cost Accounting and Control (New York: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1957), 824. —r Stanley B. Henrici, Standard Costs for Manufacturing 307 in the National Association of Cost Accountants'studies on standard costing5 and analysis of variances.6 It is the approach inherent in the uniform cost accounting system I proposed by the National Electrical Manufacturers Association.7 It is the approach of a number of "how to do it" presentations at annual meetings of the National Association of Cost Accountants.8 It is the approach of some Certified Public Accountants and industrial accountants who were interviewed in conjunction with this study. It is (New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1953), 336. William B. Lawrence, Cost Accountingy Fourth edition, revised by John W. Ruswinckel (New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1954), 659 pp. 5 How Standard Costs are Being Used Currently (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1950), 26—50. 6N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 22. "The Analysis of Cost Variances," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 2. (August, 1952), 1547-82. 7 Uniform Accounting Manual for the Electrical .Manufacturing Industry, (7th ed.) (New York: National ;Electric Manufacturers Association, 1949 , 501-29. 8A good example would be: vern Breitenbucher, "Putting Cost Accounting to Work--For Cost Control," National Association _g_f_ Cost flgccountants'Yearbook, 1946, 96—113. 308 . 9 the approach of a recent study on overhead costing and a . 10 . . recent textbook on management accounting. Finally, it is the approach adopted by the committee on cost accounting of the American Accounting Association in a statement con- . . ll cerning cost accounting for management purposes. OPERATING CONTROL IN THE FACTORY: PHYSICAL STANDARDS General Physical standards are actually the foundation of the dollar standards used in standard costing. This is especially true of direct labor and direct materials. In the case of direct labor, personnel activities take care of such matters as a complete description of various jobs (job description) and a complete description of the type of person best able to meet the requirements of the job (job specification). Methods personnel analyze each job and 9 R. Lee Brummet, Overhead Costing, 9p. git., 139-151. 1 0Robert N. Anthony, Management Accounting (Homewood, Ileinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956), 268-324. 1Committee on Cost Accounting Concepts and Standards C>f the American Accounting Association, "Tentative Statement <>f Cost Concepts Underlying Reports for Management Purposes," 2312 Accounting Review, XXXI (April, 1956), 188-190. 309 determine the best way to perform assigned tasks. Time—study personnel then time each task. After a time study the physical standards should be just about complete, for the requirements of the job and man are known, the most appro- priate methods are known, and the times to be taken are known. 'In the case of direct materials, engineering per- sonnel determine the most appropriate materials to use and the physical quantities of each type of material to produce each completed unit. Engineering personnel also handle such technical tasks as determining the output yield of various inputs, the specifications for purchased materials, and certain aspects of processing direct materials. For overhead, physical standards do present some difficulties, but they are not inSurmountable. Of special significance are methods and procedures determined by engineering personnel, setting forth the proper ways to Operate the various items of equipment. Direct Materials In the case of direct materials, the physical stan- d.ards most often heard of for purposes of cost control relate tCD excess material requisitions, yield reports, and scrap 310 reports. The value of excess material requisitions was recognized as long ago as 1887 by Garcke and Fells when they said: Before any order to manufacture is given it is advisable, as tending to produce greater economy in the cost of production, that the person best acquainted with its processes and details should estimate the probable cost to be incurred in wages and materials, in the production of the articles in question. This estimate should be a minimum rather than a maximum one, and the storekeeper, having been furnished with the particulars of it should not, without special authority, issue more material for the order than is estimated.12 Use of excess materials requisitions is considered by Gillespiel3 as a means of controlling material usage at the source. Henrici also considers these requisitions, but seems to discount them on the basis that no excess requisitions will be issued if it is permissible to complete and order with less production that was originally stipu— l4 . . . lated. Even though Gillespie and HenriCi conSider these requisitions, they do so in an incidental or fleeting manner, in the form of a digression from the usual type of 12 Emile Garcke and J. M. Fells, Factory Accounts, Fourth edition (London: CroQDy Lockwood and Son, 1893), Sl- 52. 3 Gillespie, op. cit., 420—1. 4 Henrici, pp. cit., 234. 311 variance analysis. Excess material requisitions are ordinarily of a color different from that used for ordinary requisitions, and they can be issued only on the basis of a foreman's signature. In this way, out-of-line performance is de— tected much earlier than it would be by the analysis of dollar variances. Yield reports are an excellent complement to excess material requisitions. Analyses can be made on the basis of inputs of materials, product that should have resulted, and product that did result. Depending on circumstances, such reports can be rendered daily, weekly or even monthly. Of course, the more frequently reports are turned out the earlier will notice be given of out—of—line performance. Exemplary applications of yield reports would be in bottling plants, chemical processing plants and garment manufacturing plants. Scrap and spoilage reports are also useful aids in pointing up out—of—line performance. Depending on circum* stances the reports can be issued more or less frequently. Each of these reports has been considered at one time or another in the literature on cost control, but the approach to cost control is still very much the same as for dollar 312 variance analyses. Controls related to the reports in terms of physical units are more precise and more proximate (closer to occurrence of out-of-line performance) than monthly dollar variance analyses, but all that can be corrected is the continuation of out—of—line performance which has already occurred, just as in the case of dollar variance analyses. Direct Labor Reports in physical terms for purposes of direct labor cost control relate most often to performance and idle time. G. Charter Harrison considered performance reports as early as 1920 when he said it was unnecessary to record for each employee the time taken on each Operation in order to compare it with a standard time and thus compute a measure of efficiency. He stated that all that would be necessary was a comparison of actual output per day in terms of standard time and actual time, in order to determine the efficiency of a worker during a particular 15 day Even though he did consider this physical measure of l 5G. Charter Harrison, "Cost Accounting in the New Industrial Day," Industrial Management,LIX (January, 1920), 13. 3l3 efficiency, Harrison treated it lightly and immediately returned to dollar variance analyses. Performance reports comparing actual output in terms of standard hours and actual hours used to produce the actual output yield a measure of operating performance in strict physical terms. Such reports can be issued daily, weekly, or even monthly, dependent on circumstances. To the foreman is given a report of physical performance by individual workers, and to the foreman's superior is given a summary report for the department and perhaps detailed data on exceptionally good or bad workers. To a plant superintendent could be given summary data for all depart- ments, as well as a plant summary. To each successive step in the organizational ladder is given a summary of the detailed data which was given to lower levels. Idle time reports can summarize all direct labor hours into that which was used on actual production, and that which.w§§ not utilized on actual production. The unutilized or idle direct labor hours can then be summarized bu cause, such as maintenance delay, lack of material, and power failure. These reports can be prepared for any time period or any division or subdivision of the firm. Their purpose is to show in physical terms how much of the direct 314 labor time has not been productive and the reasons therefor. Performance reports, idle time reports, and other reports of direct labor utilization in physical terms have been considered many times in the literature on cost control, but the general approach was rather well stated by Henrici, who said they "are prepared to illuminate the variances that accounting methods reveal.”16 Even though these reports might be issued earlier than dollar variance analyses, their point of View is the same, that is, to eliminate the con- tinuation of detected variances (wastes). gysrhssé Physical standards are very difficult to set for overhead costs. The reason for this is the heterogeneous nature of overhead costs and the practical impossibility of identifying individual elements of overhead with output in a specific manner. Without the possibility of physical standards such as exist for direct labor and materials, there is still a possibility of a form of physical standard for elements of overhead. Maintenance costs and delays can be effectively l6 Henrici, QR. cit., 215. 315 controlled by means of a preventive maintenance program which calls for periodic examination of all equipment items. As to when or how often equipment is to be checked or tested, this is an engineering problem related to machine capability and expected and actual use. Utilities can also be controlled by physical standards in much the same way. Information on how to use lighting fixtures can be dis- seminated to appropriate personnel, and from then on test checks on how such fixtures are utilized can be made. The same ideas are applicable to the use of power facilities, heating, air conditioning and even water usage. Various elements of indirect labor can also be subject to some form of physical control. For example, with expected output and facilities it should be known how many material handlers, inspectors, stockroom employees, helpers and even janitors are needed. These physical quotas establish the need for such men. As to their performance, it can be tested by volume of activity measured in any number of ways. The janitors' performance could easily be checked by visual observation, for example. Indirect materials can also be checked in terms of physical standards. The length of time such things as gloves, safety goggles, and foundry sand should last can be 316 established and used as a measure of control. The same ideas are applicable to cutting oils, small tools and many other elements of indirect materials. The only real limit to the use of physical standards or measures for overhead items is the usual balancing of benefit and cost. THE INTEGRATED AND CONTINUOUS APPROACH Limitations of Traditional Cost Control Cost control in the traditional sense has limited effectiveness for two reasons. In the first place, the data are stated in dollars which must be analyzed in order to determine causes and pinpoint responsibility for out—of-line performance. The analysis of productive efficiency variances must actually be broken down into physical terms in order to yield real causes and to state properly remedial measures. Secondly, the data as accumulated is past history, and becomes ancient history by the time it is analyzed to determine cause and responsibility. All that can be done is to eliminate future recurrence. These comments are relevant to all the variance. accumulations of standard costing and variable budgeting. A very good summary of cost reports that indicates their 317 limitations as expressed here was given by Professor Anthony, a member of the Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards of the American Accounting Association which prepared a statement on cost concepts for management pur- l7 . poses. Professor Anthony's comments which were an explanation and a defense of the committees' work are as follows: In this area, we first must face a familiar paradox, which can be stated as follows: Cost reports describe what has already happened; therefore they cannot be used to control events, since no one can alter or undo what has already been done; therefore, a control report cannot really control anything. He (Anthony) attempted to explain away the paradox by saying that the reports really provide the basis for actions such as "praise, criticism, or suggestions for change, all designed to improve future performance."19 He added what he called a subtle way in which cost reports can influence performance, that is, they have the effect of a l7 Supra footnote ll. 18 Robert N. Anthony, "Cost Concepts for Control," The Accounting Review, XXXII (April, 1957), 233. 19Ibid. 318 report card,20 since advance knowledge that cost control reports will be issued tends to provide a stimulus to better performance on the part of the persons to be judged. The attempt to salvage traditional cost control on the basis of a "report card effect" is admirable, but it still leaves us with an incomplete or partial concept of cost control. As will be explained later, cost control reports are part of a much broader concept of cost control, and they can be the least important part of an effective cost control scheme. Limitations of Physical Standards The physical standards which are the foundation of the pecuniary standards of accounting can be much more timely in reporting out—of—line conditions than pecuniary data, and therefore they are a much more effective control device. For this reason Billy E. Goetz has long advocated 20 The term "report card" was used by the head of the management services division of a national public accounting firm in an interview conducted in conjunction with this study. He Was referring to flexible budget reports by responsibility centers, which he considered the keystone of cost control. 21 Anthony, pp. 933., 233. 3L9 the control of direct labor and direct materials by means of physical standards and the complete abandonment of pecuniary data for control purposes.22 A typical Goetz conclusion is, "No job order cost accounting system, no process cost accounting system, and no standard cost accounting system gives as prompt and as precise control reports."23 In the case of overhead Mr. Goetz makes one con- cession; that is, he uses a combination of physical standards and flexible budgeting for control purposes. He, like Fred 24 Gardner, believes that the use of flexible budget data places him miles ahead of accounting people who, as he states it, divide, allocate, reallocate and merge costs until the components "are no longer accessible for management planning "25 and control. Neither Goetz nor Gardner seem ready to Billy E. Goetz, “Tomorrow's Cost System" included in William E. Thomas, Readings in Cost Accounting Budgeting and Control (Cincinnati, Ohio: South-Western Publishing Co., 1955), 67—80. Billy E. Goetz, Management Planning and Control (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1949), 294 pp. 23 . Billy E. Goetz, "Tomorrow's Cost System," op. cit., 75. Fred V. Gardner, Profit Management and Control (New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1955), 17—18. 25 Billy E. Goetz, "Tomorrow's Cost System," 92. cit., 67. 320 admit that flexible budgeting and responsibility cost accumulations have long been a part of accounting practice and literature. Physical standards are certainly useful for cost control purposes, but they have two limitations which are also inherent in cost accumulations. In the first place, reports in physical terms are still past history. They are not as ancient as cost accumulations, but their limits are the same, that is, they can only lead to improved future performance and the same "report card effect" of cost accumulations. The other limitation of physical standards is that the data relate to only part of a truly effective cost control system. A limitation of physical standards that is not in— herent in cost accumulations is that physical standards cannot aid in the process of making sure that input prices are controlled. Physical standards aid only in the control of physical usage. Furthermore, control of usage with physical standards can be complemented effectively with gmxzuniary data to illustrate the impact of waste to operating men. A knowledge of input prices can also help operating men in directing their effort towards the greatest cost savings. 321 Neither dollar nor physical standards provides all of the necessary ingredients for truly effective cost con— trol. Cost accountants make their mistake when they rely primarily on dollar accumulations. Goetz and those who are impressed by his arguments make their mistake when they rely primarily on physical accumulations. Both of these groups make their greatest error, though, when they approach cost control with the question what must we g9 ngw, after we take the precious time to find out what went wrong in the first place. The appropriate question which defines the correct approach is, what has gone wrong and what has already been done to eliminate those factors giving rise to out-of-line performance. This more effective approach can only be appreciated in the light of the organization structure and its various levels which will bring into focus an integration of cost and physical standards and an appreciation of the true position of cost accumulations in the overall cost control framework. The next section will consider in a general way the general principles applicable to a truly integrated and continuous system of cost control. 322 Hierarchial Ranking_and the Integration of Cost and Physical Standards At best the ideas to be expressed here are nothing more than a statement pulling together the contributions of every facet of the business organization as they relate to cost control. There is really nothing new, except perhaps a definite statement that brings many of the activities re- lated to cost control into proper focus. The approach of traditional cost control as stated by the Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards, as well as the approach of Mr. Goetz, most likely imply many of the ideas to be expressed below. It is unfortunate, however, that the most important aspects of cost control are left to implication, and are not brought together in such a way that the proper position of cost accumulations can be fully appreciated. For purposes of illustration, it is to be assumed that there are six levels in the organization structure. Each of the levels is to be considered a line of defense against out-of—line performance. The line closest to actual production is considered first, and the line furthest away from actual production is considered last. The function of each line of defense is to detect out—of-line performance and ask those in prior lines of defense what went wrong and 323 what has already been done to correct out of line performance. The first line of defense cannot ask this question for its function is to eliminate out-of—line performance before it starts. The cost control function of subsequent lines is to detect the out-of-line performance that may have occurred, and to find out if the necessary correctives have been applied, and if not to apply them immediately. The lines of defense can be identified as follows: Board of Directors Sixth President Fifth Manufacturing Vice—President Fourth Plant Manager Third Foreman Second Worker First For each line of defense the type of information required is different. Knowledge of expected results in physical and dollar terms, visual observation, accumulations of out-of-line performance in physical and dollar terms, and even the traditional income statement, all play a part in cost control. At the worker's level visual observation is paramount. A keen eye used by a worker who has a sense of responsibility and a knowledge of his task can spot impending trouble or those conditions that would inhibit 324 the attainment of expected performance. A machine that is beginning to act up, preceding operations which are moving too slowly to assure production continuity, and an impending lack of materials are all factors that can be overcome be— fore they result in out-of-line performance. At the foreman level visual observation is also im- portant, but it can be complemented by reports in physical terms. The foreman oversees the work of many, so visual observation must be on a sampling basis. With this in mind, reports of physical progress such as yield reports or per— formance reports play an important part. These physical reports are utilized to make up for the necessarily limited observation. A knowledge of pecuniary data related to the physical reports can also be of importance at the foreman level. A perfect application of a knowledge of pecuniary 'data would occur in those everpresent situations where the foreman must allocate his time in such a way as to yield the maximum benefit. In other words, a foreman must have a knowledge of pecuniary data in order that he can direct his efforts towards the greatest cost savings or the greatest sources of waste. The foreman's position is the second line of defense. He must be in a position to identify visually any potential 325 sources of out-of—line performance that workers fail to 'recognize and also identify actual waste (visually and from reports) in order to find out what has already been done to eliminate such wastes. If nothing has been done, then the foreman should take appropriate action. Thus it is seen that the foreman's position is secondary if the worker has a r—h sense of responsibility and a wary eye. Without the aid 9_ (D the worker, for one reason 9; another, the foreman would b g second-best choice for the first line 9f defense. The plant manager is ordinarily not in a position to make very extensive visual observations, so he must rely heavily on reports comparing expected and actual performance in physical and dollar terms. These reports are usually sum— maries of reports given to foremen and may also be prepared less frequently than reports given to foremen. Physical and dollar reports are both important to the plant manager; physical reports, since they represent the language of the shop, and dollar reports, since they facilitate choices in- volving the most effective utilization of time and an under- standing of the full impact of waste. Again, though, the position of the lines of defense behind the first line is the same, that is, to find out what has already been done to eliminate detected waste, and, if nothing has been done, to institute procedures necessary to eliminate the continuation 326 of the wastes that earlier lines of defense failed to recognize and eliminate. The manufacturing vice—president presumably has under him a number of plants. Visual observation in his case is of little consequence. Physical and dollar reports that compare actual and expected results are the most effective control media he has. These reports are summaries for each plant as a whole, based on the more detailed and more frequently-prepared reports that are given to plant managers. At this level it is more than likely that dollar reports are as important, if not more important, than physical re— ports,_for the manufacturing vice-president is at that level where profit—and—loss responsibility and the dollar impact of waste is beginning to be emphasized. As in all prior lines of defense, the point of view is to ask the question what has already been done to eliminate the de- tected wastes. An important factor that could have been noted earlier is that analyses of physical or dollar variances should not be necessary. Under the broad cost control system recommended here, the analysis already exists in the hands of prior lines of defense in the form of the data summarized to provide the reports to higher levels. The president's position is one of profit and loss .4 responsibility in the fullest sense of the word. To him 327 very summarized physical data concerning plant operations can be given, but more important than this is the dollar data given in the form of standard cost and flexible budget variances. Dollar data illustrate in the best possible way the full impact of waste to the dollar-minded tOp executive, 1 and prepare him for the questions that are bound to be asked by the board of directors when they receive the company's income statement showing what income was earned and what happened to the income that should have been earned (variances). The income statement which includes the variations from standard costs and the overall flexible budget reports yields the sixth line of defense, which is the point where dollar variations are of greatest significance. As usual there is no need for detailed variance analysis at this point because the variances as calculated are summaries of already-existing physical and dollar reports prepared for the more immediate lines of defense. Also, the controls applicable to these variances relate to the usual question of what has already been done, and if certain items are found to have been overlooked they will then be considered. Each level of defense becomes more and more remote Ifrom the operating departments where real control actually should take place. The only reason for the more remote 328 lines of defense is as a check on the effectiveness of the more immediate lines of defense. The more effective the immediate lines of defense are, the less important the more remote lines of defense are. In some cases, then, the more remote lines of defense can be and are taken more casually, and may eVenbeignored. The more remote lines of defense emphasize the cost accumulations related to standard cost accounting and flexible budgeting. The general position of these cost accumulations and their proper context in the broad framework of cost control should now be better appreciated. The traditional approach overemphasizes cost accumulations, while the physical approach does not appreciate their utility. Only the integrated approach presented here places both cost and physical accumulations in their prOper context. The foregoing description of six lines of defense could easily include a number of other factors. Some of these are prior to the worker's position and some come after the board of directors. In a sense the activities prior to the worker are even more fundamental to cost control than the above—mentioned lines of defense. Among these possibly more fundamental activities are the three categories of personnel administration, engineering, and production control. 329 In the case of personnel administration, there must be effective hiring and placement policies at all organi— Vzational levels. The right man for each job is the major goal here. This of course necessitates a knowledge of job characteristics (job description) and a knowledge of the man characteristics (job specifications). Very closely related to this is the engineering function of determining expected performance. In other words, there must be a knowledge of the physical relation between the various type of inputs and outputs. This knowledge is preferably determined on the basis of engineering studies. Past re- sults could also form the basis of expected performance. However expected performance is determined, it should be common or available knowledge to all levels in the organi- zation. Production control activities are also very essential to cost control. Proper production planning and control yields the appropriate quantities and qualities of inputs at the apprOpriate time. There is really no end to the relationships between the operating and facilitating agencies of any industrial firm as they relate to cost con— trol. It is believed, however, that the more important aspects have already been noted. Beyond the level of the board of directors, there 330 are the stockhOlders who can also be related to the overall cost control process. The stockholders do not receive a report of income that includes variances from standard costs, but the income statement they do receive is a measure of the firm's overall economic progress. This measure of progress,.if understood properly, should be considered the result of all the firm's activities and therefore a function of sales and the innumerable forms of waste that can be found in any business. If stockholders are not satisfied with the firm's progress they can put pressure on the board of directors to make more intensive efforts to increase income by increasing sales and/or decreasing waste. The stockholders could possibly force a change in the make-up of the board of directors or perhaps, if nOthing else could be done they could give up and dispose of their stock. Thus the stockholders can also become, at least to a limited extent, a line of defense against out—of-line performance. In summary, the six lines of defense explained above should illustrate that both dollar and physical accumulations have a place in the broad framework of cost control. However, more important that either is the visual observation of workers and their foreman. With the first lines of defense visual observation is most important. The sixth line of 331 defense, on the other hand, is aided by a report of income that shows what income was earned and what happened to that which should have been earned. In between the first and the sixth lines of defense physical standards play a more important part at the more immediate levels while dollar standards play a more important role at the more remote levels. This can be illustrated as follows: Lines of Defense Basis of Control VI Board of Directors An Income Statement Showing ‘ Variances m 1 . m A "a ’ V PreSident E E fg E The area of _ . ,g H g H Physical and IV Manufacturing Vice- {(3 e 46)) 8 Dollar Stan- Pre51dent p O O dards U) E H E: H m E 8 0‘: III Plant Manager m E m .H E m H o.u m o u H O H a U H. II Foreman o m o ,2 m 0V Q on Q4 D4 m Clo I Worker Primarily Visual Observation Of primary importance in the integrated and continuous approach to cost control is the basic change in attitude wherein the question related to variances becomes what went wrong and what has already been done to correct deviations in expected performance. When physical and dollar standards are taken in their proper context there is no need to relate their significance solely to the improvement of future 332 performance and the "report card effect”. The most appropriate position of dollar and physical standards can be appreciately only in the light of the integrated approach as presented here. The next section is designed to give more specific data concerning control of costs as it relates to direct labor and direct materials in order to lay the groundwork for a discussion on control of overhead costs. ILLUSTRATIONS OF THE INTEGRATED AND CONTINUOUS APPROACH General The development of the above general ideas and the more specific ideas to be presented about cost control are actually the result of a process of personal development and growth on the part of the author. For a long time I had been disturbed by the great reliance placed on cost accumu- lations in the literature on cost control. The use of the more immediate physical reports had great appeal, especially with reference to direct labor and material usage. Price variances were ordinarily dismissed as being essentially caused by external forces over which operating men and purchasing personnel had no control. These price variations were considered the means necessary to make 333 double-entry bookkeeping work when standard costs were not kept up to date. In the case of overhead variances, as they are usually prepared in standard costing, I believed them to possess absolutely no utility for cost control purposes due to the fact that they were broad historical averages of a great mass of unrelated items of varying fixity and variability. Without the flexible budget approaCh to over- head cost control, the control of overhead costs was, I felt, shrouded in the darkness of double-entry bookkeeping. At this point I had read a great deal of the literature on cost control. The next logical step was to conduct some interviews with actual practitioners involved in the managerial services activities of national public accounting firms. These men were: Paul Hamman, Partner and Head of Management Services Touche, Niven, Bailey and Smart, CPA's Detroit Michigan Leonard Spacek, Managing Partner and Basil Regione, Partner and Head of Administrative Services Arthur Anderson and Co., CPA's Chicago, Illinois Hugh Campbell, Partner and Edward Weise, Head of Management Advisory Services Price Waterhouse and Co., CPA's Chicago, Illinois Horace Barden, Partner Ernst and Ernst, CPA's ,Chicago, Illinois 334 In the process of these interviews the full broad implications of cost control were developed. In the first interview the merits of physical standards and pecuniary standards were brought to a head when the interviewee stated that in a facetious way one could assert that costs could be controlled without dollar accumulations. I questioned the use of the word facetious and finally we decided that reports of physical usage could be much more important for purposes of controlling direct labor and material usage. In the existing literature, the ideas of Billy Goetz seem to be thoroughly in accordance with this viewpoint. In a succeeding interview, an exchange of ideas on the need for control data at various leyglg in the organi— zation led to an appreciation of the fact that physical reports were in the language of the shop, and therefore more appropriate at organization levels close to actual performance of the work. Dollar reports were in language more appropriate for higher level management, in that they provided an excellent summary of waste in terms very familiar to the dollar-minded executive, that is, dollars and cents. Other interviews confirmed these ideas as they 335 related to direct materials and direct labor. The inability to set physical standards for overhead led to a unanimous Vconclusion that flexible budget reports were probably the most appropriate basis for accumulating data for overhead cost control. Upon returning to the academic community, I discussed these ideas with a number of people. Finally, after considerable discussion and thought, the concept of lines of defense was conceived in conjunction with the strategic importance of visual observation on the part of the worker and foreman. The introduction of and the appreciation of the strategic importance of visual observation is the most im— portant aspect of the concept of lines of defense. It brings into focus the tremendous role of worker and foremen in effective cost control, which starts before conditions get out—of-line. Furthermore, a full appreciation of the role of visual observation yields a complete turnabout in the approach to cost control. No longer is it necessary to rely only on improving future performance. Cost control is seen to be the role of operating men of whom we should ask what went wrong and what have you already done to correct the situation. Finally, the lines of defense approach presents a very understandable explanation for the non-use of cost 336 accumulations for purposes of cost control. "Cost accumulations don't even begin to motivate about ninety percent of the people for whom they are prepared", was the statement of one practitioner, and was generally agreed to by the others. The reason is that cost accumulations relate to the latter lines of defense against out—of—line perfor— mancelwhich could make them relatively insignificant if the more proximate lines of defense could be relied upon to con— duct their affairs properly. An opportunity was made available to test these ideas in three industrial concerns.27 To a certain extent they had been tested before in the interviews with public accounting practitioners and in the author's memory, which contained a number of personal experiences in the field of public accounting. Now, though, the full or complete idea was available for testing. In each case it was found that the concept developed did fit actual circumstances, although there were modifications in the approach. In one instance direct labor was considered to be of prime importance and all control efforts were directed toward it. Material and overhead costs were slighted somewhat in this case. In 2 _ , 7A. B. Dick Company, Chicago, Illinois .Automatic Electric Company, Northlake, Illinois Curtiss Candy Company, Chicago, Illinois 337 another instance direct materials and direct labor were both carefully considered due to equal importance, and indirect labor and materials were singled out as strategic elements of overhead to be controlled. In the third instance the same ideas were generally present, but a lack of familiarity with the productive processes was found to be a stumbling block for accounting personnel. Implied rather than explicitly stated was the importance attached to supervisory and operating personnel in terms of visual observation. One shortcoming found in all the interviews was that the attitude toward cost control seemed to emphasize too much the factor of improving future performance and leave only to implication the fact that a good many potential and actual out—Of—line conditions had been eliminated by operating and supervisory personnel long before cost control reports could be prepared. In succeeding pages the broad concept of cost control thus far developed will be treated in more detail as it relates to direct material, direct labor and overhead. Direct materials and direct labor will not be treated in too great detail since overhead cost control is of major importance here. The treatment of direct materials and direct labor provides an excellent framework around which to 338 build a more detailed approach to overhead cost control. It is to be assumed in all of the succeeding dis— cussions that two very fundamental aspects of cost control exist. First, effective hiring, training and placement policies are carried out in such a way as to get the right man for each job at all organizational levels. Each job must be analyzed in such a way as to yield a knowledge of the type of person necessary to fill the job. ‘Second, any effective system of cost control must incorporate worker and super- visory knowledge of expected performance on each job. This knowledge about the physical relations between several inputs (material, labor, machine hours) and their output, is determined preferably on the basis of engineering studies. These two characteristics, selection of the best people and a thorough knowledge of what performance is to be expected of them, actually form the basic framework of manufacturing cost control. Direct Materials Control of direct material costs will be built primarily around usage variances. Price variations, though, will also be considered. In the cases of usage variations the reports of physical quantities to be considered are 339 excess material requisitions and yeild reports. Illustra- tion 7 probably illustrates better than words the approach to control of material usage which is recommended. The major purpose of the illustration is to show the proper position of cost accumulations in the cost control process related to material usage. The lines of defense range from the worker to the board of directors. At the worker level visual observation is paramount, while at the board of directors' level a summary usage variance becomes the basis of control. In between the worker and the board of directors the effectiveness of visual obser— vation becomes more and more limited and it is replaced primarily by physical reports concerning excess material requisitions and yield. Dollar knowledge of relative material_prices also becomes useful as a guide to allocating effort towards the greatest cost savings. As the progression is made toward the board of directors, physical reports become more and more summarized and are complemented by a very understandable measure of the true impact of waste, that is, the dollar variance. Finally, as the shop area is left behind, the language of the shop is for all practical purposes disposed of, and is replaced by dollar variance accumulations, a more appropriate form of language at higher Illustration 7 340 Summary of Control Over Material Usage Lines of Defense II. III. IV. VI. Worker Visual Observation Sample Visual Observation Foreman Physical Reports Dollar Knowledge Sample Visual Observation Plant Physical Reports Superintendent Dollar Knowledge Dollar Reports Manufacturing Vice—President Physical Reports Dollar Reports President Physical Reports Dollar Reports Board of Directors Dollar Reports Bases of Control quality of material condition of equipment physical surroundings or condition of workplace same as above worker attitude or condition excess material requisitions yield reports relative material values same as foreman foreman attitude or condition summary of excess material requisitions summary yield reports details on strategic materials relative material values usage variance summary yield report on strategic materials summary usage variance summary yield report on strategic materials summary usage variance summary usage variance 341 Illustration 7 (cont'd) Comments on Summary of Control over Material Usage Reports rendered to superiors are made known to or are given to those being supervised. All reports are prepared in terms of personal responsibility. At each successive level reports become more summarized and they are issued less frequently. There is no need to breakdown and analyze dollar variances at higher organizational levels since the break— downs and analyses already exist in the form of physical and dollar reports rendered to the prior lines of defense. To To To To 342 Illustration 7 (cont'd) Objectives of the Summary of Control over Material Usage illustratethe proper position of cost accumulations in the cost control process. illustrate that potential and actual waste can be and is eliminated by visual observation, that is, long before physical and dollar reports are prepared. illustrate that actual wastes that evade visual ob— servation can be and are detected by physical reports. illustrate that cost accumulations occupy a residual position and show the profit impact of waste. 343 management levels. Visual observation is the most immediate form of defense available and it is relied upon to eliminate potential and actual waste even before such wastes are brought out in physical and dollar reports. Actual wastes that evade visual observation can be and are detected by physical reports. Dollar reports occupy the position of detecting the residuum, that is, the actual wastes that have evaded visual observation and physical reports. Physical and dollar reports detect practically all of the actual wastes, but their use should be directed toward eliminating continuing waste. In this way the receiver of the report will be notified of wastes, will find out which wastes have already been eliminated, as they should have been, and then he will concentrate on the elimination of the previously uncorrected waste. Illustration 7 on material usage control summarizes the position of each person in the control process. The worker, on the'basis of visual observation, should be able to detect potential and actual waste that might be caused by inferior materials, improperly maintained equipment, and even poor lighting. Foremen, too, can use visual obser- vation to detect potential and actual waste in the same 344 manner as the workmen and also by visually inspecting the attitude or condition of the workmen. Since the foreman must supervise a number of people, his visual observation must necessarily be on a sampling basis. Physical reports on excess material requisitions and yield provide a perfect complement to the necessarily limited visual observation of the foreman. Excess material requisi- tions are brought to the foreman's attention immediately, since they can be issued only on his signature. Yield reports for the foreman can be prepared on a daily basis, and they will compare physical inputs of material and physical output yield in actual and expected quantities. In cases where the foreman is forced to make a choice as to allocating his time to waste elimination, a knowledge of relative material values will help him direct his effort towards the greatest possibilities for cost saving. The plant superintendent is in a position where he must also aid in waste detection. He relies on those closer to the actual work to bear the brunt of the cost control burden, but, just in case, he checks on their work per— formance by a necessarily very limited visual observation, coupled with daily summaries of excess material requisitions, and perhaps weekly summaries of yield reports by departments 345 or responsibility centers. Dollar knowledge of relative material values is useful in order that effort can be con— centrated where the greatest cost savings lie. A monthly dollar usage variance report prepared by classes of material and departments or responsibility centers serves the purpose of summarizing the dollar impact of waste. It is possible under some circumstances that only a dollar and cents figure will awaken people to the true profit and.loss potential of cost control. Summarized, the plant superin- tendent's position is a matter of being informed about wastes, finding out what has already been done, and then taking action to eliminate previously undetected and uncorrected wastes. If a plant superintendent desires more information concerning the summary reports given to him, a simple request for the more detailed and more frequently prepared reports used by the foremen is all that is necessary. These detailed reports and a conference with foremen concerned should give the superintendent all the information he needs in order to find out if there is any basis for action on his part. The manufacturing vice—president relies on even more summarized reports, plus the details that can be provided by various plant superintendents, in order to determine if 346 there is any reason to take action. He, too, should rely on the more immediate lines of defense to take care of most cost control activities. His responsibility is the detection of undetected and uncorrected variances. Reports rendered to the vice—president would be monthly summary yield reports on strategic material, by plant, and dollar usage variances, by plant. Strategic materials might be certain kinds of shoe leather in the shoe industry, more expensive materials and furs in the garment industries, and precious metals and jewels in the jewelry industry. The president's role would be essentially the same as the vice-president's except that reports would be more summarized. Finally, the board of directors' position would also be very much the same, although monthly dollar variances as contained in an income statement showing income actually earned and income that Should have been earned (usage variance) would be the basis of any cost control activities that it might still be necessary to institute. The above presentation is only a model that could easily be modified. For example, other types of physical reports could be prepared, and some reports could be pre- pared less often or more often, or they could include more or less detail. Also, continuous physical yield reports 347 could be abandoned in favor of occasional or sample yield tests. Sample yield reports for materials involving large dollar amounts could be made more often than sample reports for small dollar items. Depending on the size of the firm there could also be more or fewer lines of defense. How— ever this may be, the general framework should be clear. Visual observation is most important, while physical reports are secondarily important, and dollar reports serve a residual position and effectively put forth the dollar impact of waste. Thus far usage variances have been considered. Price variations for materials have many dimensions different from usage variances. Usage can be determined with a fair degree of scientific precision, but prices used in setting cost standards are the best estimates of prices that will exist in the period for which the standards are being set. Errors in the estimates or the inflationary process give rise to variances over which no one in the firm has control. Such variances are more closely related to external than to internal conditions. Those price variances which are related to internal conditions can serve to indicate various internal efficiencies. In the case of the purchasing department, control is exercised over economical buying quantities and 348 methods of transportation,28 if purchasing procedures are not disturbed by internal conditions which would upset normal buying quantities and transportation methods. Internal conditions which could upset the price variance as a measure of purchasing performance are the acceptance of rush sales orders, failure of the factory to anticipate its needs, and abnormal spoilage by the factory resulting in rush purchase orders in non—standard quantities which are delivered by more expensive methods. The concept of lines of defense would fit the control process surrounding price variances with minor modifications. After the determination of economical buying quantities, economical methods of transportation and the price standards, the lines of defense would start with buyers, followed by a purchasing agent, followed by a manufacturing vice— president and then the president and board of directors. Physical standards are impossible here, so dollar standards must be relied on. A control procedure would involve the necessity for 28 The determination of buying quantities and methods of transport is a never-ending process due to changing technologies, improved knowledge, possibilities of forward buying, or a change in any one of the elements used to determine buying quantities and methods of transportation. 349 buyers to prepare memos concerning off—standard purchase prices. The memos would contain an explanation such as price change, rush order, excessive Spoilage, or inability to use preferred transportation. Such memos could be periodically reviewed by the purchasing agent, who might also receive a dollar variance report monthly. This dollar variance report could show data by classes of materials and causes of purchase price variances. The dollar variance report would be nothing more than a summary of the memos prepared by buyers. Sales personnel should be immediately notified of purchase price variances caused by accepting rush orders. Factory personnel also should be immediately notified of purchase price variances caused by abnormal spoilage or failure to anticipate needs. In this way divisions of the business will be kept aware of the fact that their activities have a direct and observable bearing on material prices. The manufacturing vice-president, the president and the board of directors each in turn will receive summaries of material price variances classified by responsibility centers and perhaps by classes of materials. At each successive line of defense the process will simply be a matter of determining the excusability of variances and 350 what has already been done to eliminate the conditions giving rise to internally controllable price variation. Comparable to the importance of visual observation in material usage variations would be, in the case of material price variations, the determination of economical quantities to buy, economical methods of transportation and the dissemination of this information to all those who can affect the attainment of economical buying methods. This information, coupled with a need for explaining the cause of all price variances, would force a consideration of possible out—of—line conditions at the time an order is placed. The functions of more remote lines of defense would be to ask questions to find out if price variations were justifiable, to determine if prior lines of defense appreciate the profit impact of off-standard prices, and to make sure that those who are able to affect price variations are well aware of the wastes that they can control. Cost control related to direct material usage and .prices involves a number of factors. After the placing of the best possible men in each occupation, the determination of physical usage standards, the determination of economical buying quantities, economical methods of transportation, and standard prices, and the dissemination of this 351 information to all affected parties, the essence of cost control lies in visual observation for material usage and the requiring of explanations for all off—standard prices at the time a purchase order is made. Physical reports of material usage aid in the detection of waste not detected by visual observation, and a review of memos relating the cause of price variations establishes a basis for determining whether or not price variations are excusable. Dollar reports occupy a residual position and_provide a perfect illustration of the profit impact of waste. The residual position of dollar reports will assume more importance if only strategic materials are reported on physically, if physical reports are prepared on a sampling basis, or if .on-the—spot memos on price variances are required only for strategic materials or for those prices which are off— standard by a stated percentage (e.g., 5 percent). Direct Labor Control of direct labor cost will be constructed primarily around usage variances. Price variations will also be given some consideration. Physical reports that will be utilized to illustrate the lines of defense concept are performance reports and idle time reports. Again an 352 illustration will prObably best illustrate the recommended approach to control of labor usage. The major purpose of Illustration 8 is to illustrate the most appropriate role of cost accumulations in the control of labor usage or efficiency. As in the case of materials, the lines of defense range from the worker to the board of directors. At the worker level visual Observation is of prime importance, while at the board of directors level a summary dollar usage variance is of prime importance. In between the worker and the board of directors visual observation is of decreasing importance due to the necessity of more limited observations. Physical reports take up the slack created by the necessarily limited observation. These physical reports relate primarily to performance and idle time, and they are in a language most appropriate for use in the shop. Within the shop dollar knowledge of wage rates is important since it can help direct effort towards the greatest cost savings. At the higher levels of the shop, dollar reports of usage variance yield a measure of the profit impact of waste which is a perfect complement to the summarized physical reports. As one leaves the shop area, the physical reports become less important, and they are replaced by reports conforming to the language of higher Illustration 8 353 Summary of Control Over Labor Usage Lines of Defense I. II. III. IV. VI. Worker Sample Visual Observation Foreman Physical Reports Dollar Knowledge Sample Visual Observation Physical Reports Plant Super- intendent Dollar Knowledge Dollar Reports Manufacturing Physical Reports Vice-President Dollar Reports Physical Reports President Dollar Reports Board of Dollar Reports Directors Visual Observation Bases of Control quality of material condition of equipment physical surroundings or condition of workplace impending bottlenecks impending lack of material same as above worker condition or attitude performance report idle time report wage rates same as foreman 'foreman attitude or condition summary performance report summary idle time report wage rates usage variance summary performance report summary idle time report summary usage variance summary performance report summary idle time report summary usage variance summary usage variance 354 Illustration 8 (cont'd) Comments on Summary_of Control over Labor Usage Reports rendered to superiors are made known to or are given to those being supervised. All reports are prepared in terms of personal responsibility. At each successive level reports become more summarized and they are issued less frequently. There is no need to breakdown and analyze dollar variances at higher organizational levels since the breakdowns and analyses already exist in the form of physical and dollar reports rendered to the prior lines of defense. 355 Illustration 8 (cont'd) Objectives of the Summary_of Control Labor Usage To illustrate the proper position‘Qf cost accumulations in the cost control process. To illustrate that potential and actual waste can be and is eliminated by visual observation, that is, long before physical and dollar reports are prepared. To illustrate that actual wastes that evade visual observation can be and are detected by physical reports. To illustrate that cost accumulations occupy a residual position and show the profit impact of waste. 356 organization levels, that is, dollar reports. These dollar reports cannot be improved upon to illustrate the true impact of waste on profits. Visual observation is the most proximate form of defense available and it is relied upon to eliminate potential and actual waste even before such wastes are brought out in physical and dollar reports. Actual wastes that evade visual observation can be and are detected by physical reports. Dollar reports occupy the position of detecting the residuum, that is, the actual wastes that have evaded Visual observation and physical reports. Physical and dollar reports detect practically all of the actual wastes, but their use should be directed toward efliminating continuing waste. In this way the receiver of the report will be notified of wastes, will find out which wastes have already been eliminated, as they should have been, and then he will concentrate on the elimination of the previously undetected waste. In the illustration on labor usage the position of each person in the control process is clearly illustrated. The worker, on the basis of visual observation, is able to detect potential and actual labor waste related to quality of materials, condition of equipment and workplace, impending 357 bottlenecks and impending lack of materials. The foreman as the second line of defense relies on sample visual observa— tion of the same things the worker should be watching for, as well as of the condition and attitude of the worker. Physical reports on daily worker performance and daily departmental idle time by causes effectively complement visual observation. The same is true of wage rate knowledge which helps the foreman direct his effort. The plant superintendent complements his necessarily limited observations with weekly departmental summaries of performance reports and weekly departmental summaries of idle time reports. Dollar knowledge of wage rates and dollar reports of monthly labor usage variances by departments or responsibility centers are also useful at the plant super— intendent level. The dollar reports present an excellent technique directed toward making people realize the full profit impact of wasted labor. To the manufacturing vice-president are given monthly physical reports summarizing labor performance by plant and idle time reports by plant. These reports, plus a monthly dollar variance report by plant, give the vice—president ythe information necessary to find out what has already been ¢flone to eliminate wastes, and what wastes are still Ill till, . I'd-II, 1‘11; I . 358 continuing. If the vice-president desires more detail concerning either physical or dollar reports, all he needs are copies of the information given to and consultation with prior lines of defense. The president and board of directors rely primarily on dollar reports which are more summarized. Their roles are similar to that of the vice—president, but they are more remote; The key to the board of directors position is an income statement which exhibits the waste or profit lost through inefficient use of labor. As in the case of material usage, the illustration on labor usage is a model which can easily be modified. Physical reports other than performance or idle time reports can be prepared. Reports can be prepared more or less often. More or fewer lines of defense can be used, depending on the organization. Continuous physical reporting may be abandoned in favor of sample tests. Even with such modifi- cations the general framework, indicating the primary importance of visual observation, the secondary importance of physical reports, and the residual importance of dollar reports, is left undisturbed. Labor price variations have not yet been considered. Relatively this variance is of little consequence, since 359 wage rate determination is largely an external problem of collective bargaining and community wage levels. The variance itself is primarily a means of making the double— entry system work when standards are not kept up to date. At least two aspects Of labor price variances might be useful for control purposes. These are in the use of non-- _preferred men, and overtime. The use of a non—preferred man is a case where a $3.00 an hour man is used for a $2.00 an hour job. Control of these two causes of labor price variances can be worked into the lines of defense framework with minor modifications. Lines of defense might work from the foremen through the board of directors. In such cases it would be the foreman's job to keep production moving smoothly in order to avoid those rushes or bottlenecks which create a need for using non-preferred men or for overtime work. In any case where non-preferred men are utilized, the foreman should be required to prepare a job—change notice which details the causes and the men involved. In cases where overtime work becomes necessary the foreman should be required to obtain approval for the overtime from his superior. Reasons for use of non—preferred men and overtime work can be uneven production caused by unexpected bottlenecks, ' lit! 1!: I. Ifil .. 1.1%.? . . J 1i. .. . 360 poor production scheduling, or the acceptance of rush orders. Unexpected bottlenecks can be caused by poor worker performance, delay in making decisions by super- visors, poor scheduling, machine breakdowns, and lack of materials. With the foreman required to explain these out—of—line conditions, notice will be given to higher lines of defense, and all related parties will become aware of their impact on wage rate variances. This awareness, coupled with the necessity to explain the reasons for the variances, should provide later lines of defense with the information necessary to determine not only the excusability of the variances controllable by the firm, but whether or not the causes of unexcusable rate variances have been eliminated. Dollar accumulations of the rate variations, classified by cause and responsibility centers, show the dollar impact of waste and yield a starting point from which later lines of defense can begin to ask questions concerning the excusability of internally controllable variances. In many cases, use of non-preferred men and overtime work are excusable as being the least expensive way out of a bottleneck, but the cause of the bottleneck is the condition that must still be rectified. Control of labor costs in terms of usage or prices 361 relates to a number of factors. Of primary significance are selection and placement policies, training, the development of preferred methods of operation which can be given standard times, and production scheduling activities. With these points in mind, the essence of labor cost control relates to visual observation and required explanations for the use of overtime and non—preferred men. Physical reports of labor usage aid in the detection of waste not detected by visual Observation, and a review of explanations concerning non-preferred men and overtime establishes a basis for determining the excusability of wage rate variances. Dollar reports, as stated before, occupy a residual position and provide notice of waste in terms of profit and loss. The cost accumulations of accounting are thus seen in their true light as a residual for the more remote lines of defense against out—of-line performance. Overhead Control of overhead costs presents many problems which are not present in the case of direct materials or direct labor. In the first place, overhead costs represent a variety of unrelated items which vary in every conceivable ‘way with output. Secondly, overhead costs are not susceptible 362 to the type of physical measures applied to direct materials and direct labor. Finally, controllability of overhead costs varies in accordance with organization levels. Depreciation and taxes on buildings and equipment are controllable by the committee or persons who authorize capital expenditures. Insurance costs are controllable by an insurance committee or the person who authorizes insurance expenditures. Salaries of supervisors and clerks are controllable by those who establish rates of pay. Workers and foremen can cOntrol the costs of operating equipment and facilities and other operating costs. Fringe benefits, payroll taxes, compensation insurance and personal property taxes are hardly controllable by company personnel, for they are usually determined by factors external to the company. In order to present a sound framework encompassing the control of overhead costs, a summary has been prepared to illustrate the factors involved and their relative positions in Illustration 9. The same general framework developed for direct material and direct labor has been retained because of its general applicability. In fact, the only reason for discussing direct materials and direct labor was that they presented the easiest and perhaps most Illustration 9 363 Summapy of Control Over Overhead Costs Categories of Overhead Cost Bases of Control Operatinggor Physical Prior to Accounting Accumulations Expenditures for Factory Pre—expenditure justification by the Buildings and Equipment top-management committee which authorizes capital expenditures. Readiness to Serve Costs The committee or person who approves the number of personnel and minor equipment expenditures. Visual ob— servation (by supervisors) of the personnel at work can establish the continuing need for and efficiency of personnel. Costs of Operating Equipment and Facilities Engineers or the company from which equipment is purchased should determine Operating Department » proper methods of using equipment. A Costs preventive maintenance program could 2 also be set-up. Visual test checks on actual use can be made by engineers, maintenance men, and departmental supervisors in order to establish a basis for cost control. Costs covered here would be all those incurred to operate the equipment and fixtures. Other Operating Costs The residual, primarily supplies con- trollable on the basis of requisitions signed by supervisors and visual Ob- servation of actual use by the super- visor. Readiness to Serve Costs Same as producing departments Service Department Costs of Operating Equipment and Facilities Costs Same as producing departments Other Operating Costs Same as producing departments Office of Plant Superintendent Other overhead COStS Same as service departments foice of Manufacturing Vice-President Same as service departments Categories of Overhead Cost Expenditures for Factory Buildings 364 Illustration 9 (cont'd) Summary of Control Over Overhead Cost and Equipment Operating De— partment Costs Service Depart— ment Costs Other Overhead Costs Bases of Control Accounting Accumulations of Cost First Level Second Level Third Level Post—expenditure {Wasted justification on the Capacity basis of revenues and (\Cost Variance costs arising out of previously approved capital expenditures Regular recurring comparisons of im— portant costs in Overhead terms of the most Budget appropriate output Monthly flex— (Price) measure ible budget Variance reports for each responsi- Overhead bility center Efficiency ariance Perhaps also a rotating sample of less important items in terms of the most appropriate output measure 365 understandable way to develop the integrated and continuous approach to cost control, The succeeding discussion will utilize the concepts previously develOped as a point of departure. Necessary modifications will be made to allow for categories of overhead, lack of physical standards and the matter of controllability. The categories of overhead chosen (Illustration 9) are 1) expenditures for factory buildings and equipment, 2) operating department costs, 3) service department costs, and 4) other overhead cOsts. The bases of control are divided into operating or physical, which are prior to accounting accumulations, and the accounting accumulations of cost. Accounting accumulations, Which still occupy a residual position in cost control, are divided into three levels. The three levels are successive refinements of the residual position of accounting accumulations. In the case of capital expenditures the Operating or physical basis of control is the program of pre—expenditure justification utilized by the company. The accounting bases of control are after the fact and aid only as a guide to future action, if they aid at all. First and foremost is the process of post-expenditure justification. This is a process of accumulating the revenues (cost savings) and 366 costs arising out of the previously approved capital expenditures in order to use hindsight as a basis for future expenditure decisions. The other level of accounting control (there are only two for capital expenditures) is the accumulation of a wasted capacity cost variance. This wasted capacity cost variance should be based on an average of sales expectations since it represents the overhead con- cept most closely related to capital expenditures. Expected utilizationcnmm five life of capital equipment is the capacity figure utilized in making capital expenditure decisions, and thus it should be used for determining the wasted capacity cost variance related to capital expenditure decisions. The ability of actual production to absorb all of the costs of capital equipment will provide a sort of overall measure of post—expenditure justification. In addition to the costs of depreciation connected with capital expenditures,there are other costs which should be considered. These are the prOperty taxes and insurance costs which are automatically incurred on the basis of factory building and equipment expenditures. All three of these costs, depreciation, property taxes, and insurance on capital equipment, are controllable by the top management committee which authorizes capital expenditures. Therefore such 367 committee should be charged with the responsibility for these costs via post expenditure justification and the wasted capacity cost variance. The average expected sales concept used here is the same as the cycle overhead concept, but in this case it refers only to long—lived assets. Since long-lived assets have varying lives, the average sales expectation concept includes not only an average of expected sales, but also an average of the lives of long—lived assets. Theoretically each capital asset Or related groups of capital assets could be worked into individual wasted capacity cost variances. Such a theoretical refinement would not only be unmanageable without great expenditure of effort, but it would also be impractical due to the relation of cost to benefit received. The wasted capacity cost variance has utility only in terms of yielding an overall approach to the dollar impact of waste in capital expenditure decisions. For control as such it has little utility, except perhaps as a means of illustrating the overall importance of capital expenditure justification. Therefore, from the pragmatic point of view, an average of the lives of long-lived assets would be justifiable. The accounting accumulations relevant to post-expenditure '1‘— '1.”_____..-.., . 368 justification of individual capital expenditures are much more important control—wise than the capacity cost variance. Post—expenditure justification yields data related to individual cases which can be utilized in terms of improving future similar expenditure decisions. The real basis of control for capital expenditures is not an accounting accumulation, but an intensive study of all the factors surrounding an expenditure decision before the actual decision is made. Accounting can help here, but only in terms of trying to quantify the quantifiable elements of expected revenue, expected cost savings, and expeCted costs involved in a capital expenditure decision. The second category of overhead costs exhibited in Illustration 9 is for operating departments. Within operating departments, costs are divided into three categories which are very appropriate for control purposes. The categories are l) readiness to serve costs, 2) costs» of Operating equipment and facilities, and 3) other operating costs. Operating or physical bases of control which are prior to accounting cost accumulations are different for each of these three categories. Readiness to serve costs are controllable by the committee or person who approves the number of personnel and minor equipment -.ws-$i is IT‘" ' 369 expenditures. Visual observation by supervisors can establish the continuing need for and efficiency of such personnel. Control of minor equipment expenditures can be achieved on the basis of a very modified capital expenditure justification program which would establish the need for such minor equipment (replacement or expansion), and then visual Observation by foremen and plant superintendents could be used to check if the equipment was being used in accordance with instructions. Visual observation could also be used to establish whether the equipment was needed in the first place by simply observing if the equipment is being used in the manner and to the extent believed necessary to establish the need for the equipment. If it is found that unnecessary equipment was purchased, a correction can be made in the process through which need is established. Operating and physical bases of controlling the costs of operating equipment and facilities are primarily related to the instructions established for use of the equipment. These instructions, Which could include a preventive maintenance program, can be determined by engineers or the seller of the equipment. Visual test checks on how instructions are followed yield a fundamentally important basis of control. These visual tests can be made by 370 engineers, maintenance men, and departmental supervisors. The costs covered here would include all those costs incurred in the Operation of equipment and fixtures. Examples would be power for lighting fixtures, power or fuel for air conditioning or heating fixtures, power for all machinery and equipment used in the process of manu— facture, and Operating supplies such as cutting oil. The residual operating department overhead costs are primarily supplies. They are controllable on the basis of requisitions signed by supervisors and visual obser— vation of actual use by the same supervisors. Control of the three categories of operating department costs rests primarily on the use of operating or physical bases of control. This means essentially the determination and dissemination of operating instructions and visual obser- vation to test the ability of subordinates to carry out instructions. The accounting accumulations of costs are only useful as test checks of how well prior lines of defense have performed their duties. These accounting accumulations can exist in three levels. First, there is a process of concentrating attention on individually important elements. Second, there is the monthly summary approach known as 371 flexible budgeting, and third, there is the very overall approach of overhead variances which are intended to illustrate the total dollar impact of waste. Regular recurring comparisons of important or large elements of overhead costs on the basis of the most appropriate output measures can serve as an accounting check of the efficacy of operating or physical controls. Indirect labor is often subject to this form of comparison.29 Other elements of overhead not as important individually as indirect labor, and therefore not necessary to check as often, can be checked on the basis of a rotating sample. For example, if there are ten other items to check, two or three items can be tested in one period, and dropped in a successive period when two or three other items are tests checked. In this way all items will be tested intensively at one time or another, in order to determine if operating or physical controls are functioning as intended. 29 Curtiss Candy Company of Chicago checks the re— lationship of indirect labor to physical production on a weekly basis. Catepillar Tractor Company checks the relation of indirect labor to direct labor daily as reported in C. A. Woodley, "Organizing for Efficient Production and Effective Cost Control", New Controls For Fixed and variable Costs, American Management Association Production Series No. 178 (Papers presented at the March 1948 Production Conference of the American Management Association), 1948, 10. 372 The flexible budget, which is the second level of accounting control, cannot ordinarily be used to test—check operating and physical controls in the same manner as regular recurring or rotating sample comparisons. This is true since flexible budgets covering the costs controllable within a responsibility center are ordinarily related to one overall output measure, such as direct labor dollars, direct labor hours, or machine hours. Intensive study of individual items may require analyses in output measures differing from those used in the flexible budget. For example, labor hours might be the basis of flexible budget computations, but cutting oils might be better tested in terms of machine-hours. Another reason why flexible budgets cannot serve the function of regular recurring or rotating sample comparisons is that flexible budget reports are usually prepared on a monthly basis, while the comparisons might be necessary on a daily or weekly basis. However this may be, flexible budget reports do provide an excellent approach to detecting those out-of-line conditions not detected by operating or physical controls, or the first level of accounting controls. Flexible budgets are prepared for each responsi- 373 bility center, and within each responsibility center costs are classified by object of expenditures. Comparisons are made between budgeted and actual amounts and the variations are used as a starting point in those discussions intended to find out what has already been done to alleviate out—of-line conditions. The third and last level of accounting control for operating department overhead costs involves the ”overhead budget variance” and the ”overhead efficiency variance." The summary nature of these variances for all practical purposes eliminates any control features, except perhaps the possibility of illustrating the over—all profit impact of waste in overhead costs which could bring forth a fuller realization of waste and thus yield an important pressure for cost control on the prior lines of defense. Overhead costs applicable to operating departments are thus primarily controlled by operating or physical bases including modified expenditure justification programs, determination and dissemination of operating instructions, and visual observation. Accounting controls are designed to detect all wastes, but their importance is related to the residual out—of—line conditions not previously corrected before or after they occurred. This same approach can be applied to service department overhead 374 costs as well as costs within the offices of the plant superintendent and the manufacturing vice—president. The only real difference would be that readiness to serve costs will be of much greater importance in non-operating departments than costs of operating equipment and facilities are in production departments. The lines of defense concept thus far developed for Overhead costs is somewhat different from that developed for direct labor and direct materials. A summary of the lines of defense approach in a form more comparable to that used for direct labor and direct materials is as follows: 375 Lines of Defense Bases of Control Primary Operating or Physical a) committees or person who approves capital-expenditures or readi- ness to serve costs. b) determination and dissemination of_operating instructions. c) visual observation Secondary or Residual Accounting Accumulations of Cost a) for capital expenditures 1) post—expenditure justification 2) wasted capacity cost variance b) for all other expenditures 1) regular recurring or rotating sample comparisons 2) flexible budget reports 3) overhead budget and efficiency variance A somewhat more detailed approach to the lines of defense concept can be found in illustration 10 which is, patterned after the illustrations presented earlier for direct materials and direct labor. Illustration 10 covers only one cost category in the operating departments, but the extension to the other categories of overhead costs would be essentially the same. The process presented here is again a model which can be changed to fit circumstances. Of major importance 376 Illustration 10 Summary of Control Over Operating Departmenp Overhead Costs Related to the Operation of Eguipment and Facilities Lines of Defense III. IV. VI. VII. Prior to Worker Worker Foreman .r 3. "’ ‘“\/”“ \r“ Plant Superintendent; l Manufacturing vice- president President Board of Directors /*—*‘”“—m r"‘\ r—” Bases of Control Preparation and dissemination of instructions on the use of equip- ment and facilities Preventive maintenance program Visual Observation of condition of equipment and facilities Visual observation of condition of equipment and facilities, and worker performance Dollar Reports Regular recurring reports on indivi— dually important costs Regular recurring reports on less important costs on the bases of a rotating sample Flexible budget reports Same as foreman except for more limited visual observation and summarized dollar reports Summarized flexible budget reports Summarized flexible budget reports Monthly overhead budget variance and overhead efficiency variance 377 is the residual position of accounting data. These data aid only in detecting those wastes not previously detected by the operating and physical bases of control and in illustrating the dollar impact of waste. Physical standards as used in overhead cost control are quite different from those used in the case of direct materials and direct labor. In all cases the preparation of Operating instructions and making these instructions known (essentially a training process) is of great importance. After these instructions there is nothing in the case of overhead costs to correspond to excess material requisitions, yield reports, performance reports, or idle time reports, except perhaps the regular recurring or rotating sample cost comparisons. Reliance must be placed on the worker performing his tasks properly, the ability of supervisory personnel and the accumulations of cost accounting. Price variances for overhead costs have not been separately considered here. This is because the only items subject to control are indirect labor and indirect materials, and the control over their prices is essentially the same as for direct labor and direct materials. The prices of practically all other overhead inputs are of no consequence for control purposes, for they are related to factors external 378 to the business (wage or salary changes), or are taken care of in the process of expenditure justification. SUMMARY Control of factory costs does not proceed from an analysis of standard cost variances or flexible budget variances. This is especially true of overhead costs where the standard cost variances are an average of many un- related items of varying variability and varying fixity. Flexible budget reports for overhead cost control are somewhat useful in that they provide cost reports concerning budgeted and actual costs by responsibility centers. These reports are prepared on a monthly basis, which restricts their utility to the possibility of improving future per« formance since the usual presumption is that the cost accumulations provide the basic means of detecting waste. The "report card effect" attributable to flexible budget reports seems to improve the position of flexible budget reports as a cost control device. However, standard cost variances and flexible budgets represent only a part of a truly effective cost control program. In fact, they usually represent the least important aspects of cost control. Cost control includes these 379 accounting reports, but they are subordinate to other more important factors such as preventive cost control, physical reporting and visual observation. Preventive cost control includes proper hiring and placement policies at all organizational levels, employee training programs, capital expenditure justification programs, the determination of operating instructions covering the use of equipment and facilities, and the dissemination of information on expected performance (perhaps tied to a wage incentive) to employees. For direct materials and direct labor physical usage standards based on engineering studies are useful for pre— ventive cost control. After the preventive cost control program comes visual observation of operations by workers and supervisors in order to detect potential and actual waste. In the case of direct labor and materials physical reports concerning yield, excess material requisitions, performance and idle time can be used to detect wastes that evade visual obser- vation. These physical reports are not possible in the case of overhead costs. The control process for direct costs involves in succession preventive cost control, visual observation, physical reports and then dollar reports (standard cost variances). The overhead cost control process dun—-J-MWJ' | 380 skips physical reports and involves in succession preventive cost control, visual observation and dollar reports. Over— head dollar reports relate to post—expenditure justification, intensive studies of individual costs, flexible budgets, and standard cost variances. Intensive studies of individual elements of overhead costs on a continuing or rotating sample basis are the overhead counterpart to the physical reports possible with direct labor and direct materials. The cost control processes for each of these cost groupings can be summarized as follows: (’Preventive Cost Control Visual Observation Direct Costs { Physical Reports Dollar Reports (Standard Cost Variances) Preventive Cost Control Overhead Costs Visual Observation Accounting Reports The accounting reports for overhead cost control can be summarized as follows: 381 Capital Expenditures l) post—expenditure justification 2) wasted capacity cost variance All Other Overhead Costs / Accounting Reports 1) regular recurring or rotating sample comparisons 2) flexible budget reports 3) overhead budget and efficiency variances The lack of physical reports in the case of overhead costs is offset somewhat by intensive study of individual, costs on the basis of regular recurring or rotating sample comparisons of budgeted and actual costs, but there is no denying that there is a great need for more reliance on preventive cost control, faith and confidence in supervisory personnel, and perhaps the "report card effect” of flexible budget responsibility accumulations. As summarized here, cost control does not begin with accounting accumulations of cost. Cost control in a sense ends with accounting accumulations which are designed to detect wastes which have evaded visual observation, physical reports (direct costs), and recurring analyses of individual overhead costs. The position of accounting accumulations is residual with regard to the detection of waste, for the 382 question that must come from accounting reports is what has already been done to eliminate these wastes and not what must HE dB to eliminate these wastes. The only other function of accounting accumulations in the process of cost control is to illustrate the full profit impact of waste to the dollar—minded executive. rm @5973 “I “m" CHAPTER VII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Throughout this dissertation the emphasis has been on overhead costing for income measurement and cost control. Chapter Two, on the development of overhead costing, illu- strates how relatively unimportant income measurement was in the early development of overhead costing. The origins of overhead costing involve the determination of selling prices and the need for cost control. To a large extent accountants accepted for income measurement whatever figures were derived for other cost finding purposes. Price determination was the most important factor in the early period of overhead costing. In the beginning manufacturing overhead was combined with commercial overhead and a desired profit in an.all-inclusive percentage. The all-inclusive percentage was applied to prime costs (direct materials and direct labor) in order to derive the "hoped for" selling price. With the advent of competition, price setting had to be more scientific; thus the progressive accumulation of costs up to selling prices had to be sub— stantially changed. First overhead cost as a whole had to 384 be considered in terms of its component parts, including the separation of manufacturing and commercial overhead; then wastes or costs of inefficiencies were eliminated from selling price computations; and finally out—of-pocket cost pricing came to be used under conditions where it was deemed appropriate. In conjunction with the rise of increasingly com- petitive conditions around the turn of the nineteenth century, there arose a need for and an interest in cost control. Early evidence of cost control was the separation of commercial'and manufacturing overhead in order to separate manufacturing from commercial efficiency. Church's supplee mentary rate was also intended as a cost control device or "barometer of efficiency". The supplementary rate was changed into a dollar measure of idle capacity costs, which were removed from production costs in order to derive a unit cost that varied with shop efficiency; thus the supplementary rate was changed in order to yield two measures of efficiency; 1) a dollar amount of idle capacity which varied with product marketability (commercial efficiency). 2) a unit cost which varied with shop efficiency (technical efficiency). The next steps in the development of overhead cost control were standard costing and the accumulation of costs 385 by responsibility centers. In the development of overhead costing Church's supplementary rate led a double life. The supplementary rate was an inextricable part of the evolution of the capacity concepts used in income measurement, as well as a very important element in the evolution of cost control. The capacity concepts which grew out of the supplementary rate are the practical capacity concept, the normal capacity concept, and the cycle capacity concept. Practical capacity emphasized the physical output potential of facilities, while normal capacity and cycle capacity emphasized the average cyclical sales expectations during the useful life of facilities. The practical capacity concept is based on the determination of those costs applicable to physically unused facilities or fixed costs. The normal capacity con- cept is based on the determination of a long—run basic price, and the cycle capacity concept is based on an income measurement theorywhich states that fixed manufacturing costs should be averaged over a cycle of years. The major conclusions of this study are to a large extent derived from the historical develOpment of overhead costing. In general terms the conclusions are as follows: 1) The income measurement aspects of overhead costing 386 are neither fully developed nor separated from the problems of price determination. 2) The cost control aspects of overhead costing have not yet been developed (at least in the literature) to a point where the real significance of cost accumulations is known and appreciated. These general conclusions and the more specific con- clusions which will follow are the natural outgrowth of the two objectives of this dissertation: l) to provide a more reasoned approach to overhead costing and income measurement with special emphasis on the fixed element of overhead cost, and, 2) to provide a meaningful approach to the position of overhead cost accumulations in a cost control system. Today the most prevalent capacity concept used in measuring income is the normal capacity concept. As a re— sult the accounting for income measurement is attached to the determination of a long-run basic price rather than to the measurement of income. The most objectionable feature of the normal capacity concept is the treatment of over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs. The advocates of normal capacity say that over— and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs are gains or losses due to greater or less than average expected use of facilities. However, the true meaning of overabsorbed fixed overhead costs would be costs recovered 387 in this period and not to be recovered in the future; and the true meaning of underabsorbed fixed costs would be costs not recovered in this period which are to be recovered in future periods. The true meaning of over— and underabsorbed fixed overhead, as stated above, is the only rational ex— planation of over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead that would fit the price determination foundations of normal capacity. In addition, the only treatment of over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs that is consistent with the long-run selling price foundation of normal capacity is the deferred charge and deferred credit treatment used under the cycle capacity concept. The treatment of over— and underabsorbed fixed over» head as gains and losses brought on the "direct costing controversy", one of the greatest controversies ever to concern the measurement of income. The advocates of direct costing were upset by the effect on income measurement of over— and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs being treated as gains and losses. The changes recommended by the advocates of direct costing involved the complete abolition of over— and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs on the basis of a theory which considered fixed overhead costs as costs of a period and not costs of production. To support their til, '. I I may”. .- .' 21"‘1‘? .1 388 ideas the advocates of direct costing used a break-even or marginal approach to income measurement. Unfortunately, those advocating direct costing did not recognize that neither marginalism nor break—even analysis is a form of income measurement. Marginalism is a technique designed to concentrate on the strategic factors involved in the short-run price and output decisions of a firm. Break—even analysis is essentially a process which focuses attention on the strategic factors involved in short-run decision making. Both marginalism and break—even analysis are short—run decision-making processes related to income maximization, which is a far cry from income measure- ment—-a long—run concept. The lack of consideration given to fixed costs by marginalism and break—even analysis does not mean that fixed costs are not costs of production, it only means that fixed costs are not relevant to short-run decision-making. The fact that fixed costs are costs of production and allocable to production is a point made by economists 1 As explained in Chapter Four even a fixed-variable segregation of costs is not adequate for decision-making purposes. Fixed costs do vary with time and executive decisions and most decisions have long-run implications which demand a consideration of fixed costs. 389 and others when they consider the problems of public utility rate-making and the rational foundations of the Robinson— Patman Act. In both of these cases the problem is one of allocating fixed charges to products or services. As pointed out in Chapter Four, some of the early pioneers in the field of industrial management explicitly stated that fixed manufacturing costs were costs of production and therefore allocable to production. The defenders of the traditional treatment of fixed overhead costs for income measurement rested their case on the logic involved in the economic facts of life, that is, fixed costs are necessary for production and therefore they cannot be considered as other than costs of production. As to the determination of how much of the fixed costs were costs of production, the defenders of traditional accounting utilized the cycle and practical capacity concepts. Under cycle capacity over— and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs 'are treated as deferred credits and deferred charges, thus eliminating the irrational effect on income measurement of over- and underabsorbed fixed overhead costs being treated as gains and losses. Under practical capacity the portion of fixed overhead costs which represent the unutilized physical output potential is considered as a loss due to 390 idle capacity. The cycle capacity concept averaged fixed overhead costs over production, while the practical capacity concept removed from production costs those fixed costs represented by unutilized physical output potential. The defenders of traditional accounting thus rested their case on sheer logic (fixed costs are incurred for production) and the cycle or practical capacity concepts. With the above brief summary of the direct costing controversy, the following more specific conclusions on overhead costing and income measurement can be made. 1) The advocates of direct costing were correct in maintaining that the normal capacity concept pro- duced irrational results for income measurement purposes. 2) The defenders of traditional accounting were correct in maintaining that fixed overhead costs were costs of production, but incorrect when they utilized the practical and cycle capacity concepts. 3) Both Opponents and proponents of direct costing were incorrect when they implicitly or explicitly assumed the following: a) a fixed-variable cost segregation is best for income measurement b) all fixed costs are related to long-lived asset acquisitions (fixed assets) c) unit costs should not be allowed to vary with volume. The normal overhead concept is not appropriate for income measurement because it is based on a long-run average basic price which is not necessarily correct for income 391 measurement purposes. In addition, the average cyclical sales expectations of normal capacity demand a deferred charge and deferred credit treatment for under- and over— absorbed fixed overhead, rather than a gain or loss treatment. The cycle overhead concept is not appropriate for income measurement because it averages out of existence the econ— omic facts of life for individual Operating periods. Cost applicable to the production of the current year could be applied to the production of the future, and costs applicable to the production of the future could be applied to the production of the present by the cycle capacity concept. The practical capacity concept is not appropriate for income measurement purposes because physical output potential is essentially the same as the "physical life" of assets. For income measurement purposes "useful life” is appropriate for amortizing the costs of long-lived assets—~not "physical life or physical capacity". For purposes of income measurement overhead costs should be classified as l) acquisition costs of long—lived assets (fixed assets), including insurance and property taxes on long—lived assets. 2) indivisible cost inputs or "chunk costs" 3) all other overhead costs; these are primarily the 392 costs of operating equipment and facilities. Fixed asset acquisition costs should be allocated to production on the basis of a unit of output depreciation scheme or an approximation thereof, which would be the cycle capacity concept. Indivisible cost inputs ("chunk costs") should be allocated to the production they give rise to. ”Chunk costs" are wholely applicable to any volume of output within the volume range for which ”chunk costs" are absolutely necessary productive inputs. On the basis of indivisible cost inputs, unit costs should be allowed to fluctuate with production volume. The remaining overhead costs should be applied to actual output, for they give rise to and are necessary costs of producing actual output. The objective of accounting for income measurement is to match the results (revenues) and the sacrifices (costs) involved in the process of production. A prOper calculation of costs must include the best possible means of allocating factory overhead costs to production. The methods commonly used for overhead cost allocation today have been shown to be inappropriate for income measurement. The method prOposed here is considered to be a fundamental improvement. The change in method as recommended can hardly be considered an immaterial refinement in the process of income measurement, 393 for the possibility of losses or gains due to fixed cost absorption would be effectively eliminated. In the preceding pages the first general conclusion of this dissertation was considered in more detail. The income measurement aspects of overhead costing were shown to be neither fully developed nor separated from the problems of price determination. In succeeding pages the second general conclusion of this dissertation will be considered in more detail. The cost control aspects of overhead costing have not yet been developed to a point where the real significance of cost accumulations is known and appreciated. The control of overhead costs is usually presented as starting from the overhead variances of standard costing and the overhead variances associated with the responsibility accumulations of flexible budgeting. Actually the reverse is and should be true——overhead cost control should end, not begin with, the cost accumulations of accounting. Prior to the secondary or residual position of cost accumulations are the operating or physical bases of over- head cost control. The operating or physical bases of overhead cost control include preventive cost control and visual observation. Preventive cost control includes proper 394 hiring and placement policies at all organization levels, employee training programs, capital expenditure justification programs, the determination of operating instructions covering the use of equipment and facilities, and the dissemination of information on expected performance to employees. Visual observation by workers and supervisors is intended to detect potential and actual waste. Together preventive cost control and visual observation are intended to prohibit the occurrence of out-of-line performance. Visual observation is also used to detect out-of—line conditions as soon as they do occur in order that corrective steps may be taken immediately. The position of cost accumulations is residual or secondary in that many potential and actual out—of—line conditions are detected and eliminated long before cost reports can be prepared. Cost reports are useful in detecting previously undetected out—of-line performance. The question that should be asked when cost reports are received is what has been done to eliminate these wastes which have been detected, and not what must pp g9 to elim— inate the detected wastes. As indicated in Chapter Four, the control of costs is perhaps the most important phase of accounting for an industrial enterprise. Anything which can be done academically and professionally in order to 395 present and illustrate an integrated system of cost control must be done. The control process for overhead costs as described above would involve in order of importance and applicability 1) preventive cost control 2) visual observation 3) accounting reports The accounting reports for overhead cost can be summarized as follows: Reports for Capital Expenditures l) post-expenditure justification 2) wasted capacity cost variance Reports for All Other Overhead Costs 1) regular recurring or rotating sample cost comparisons 2) flexible budget reports 3) overhead budget and efficiency variances In each of the two categories of overhead costs the reports listed first are of primary importance, for they are prepared earlier and are more specific in pinpointing out—of— line conditions. The latter reports are useful as broad or summarized indications of waste which illustrate in the best possible way the profit impact of waste. The specific conclusions on control of overhead costs which can be made as a result of this study are: 1) Overhead cost control does not proceed from the cost accumulations of accounting. 2) Preventive cost control and visual observation ' are more important in the control of overhead costs than are cost accumulations. 3) Cost accumulations are of residual importance in the control of overhead costs. 4) Cost accumulations are extremely useful indicators of the profit impact of waste. In the preceeding pages general and specific con- clusions were made concerning each of the two objectives of this dissertation. These conclusions should be of signifi— cance for academic, industrial and public accountants. Academic accountants should be interested in the conclusions on both income measurement and cost control in order that students may be given a more complete understanding of two very important aspects of accounting for overhead costs. Industrial accountants should be especially interested in the conclusions on cost control, for cost control is one of the most important phases of internal management to which industrial accountants can make a contribution. Public accountants should be especially interested in the conclusions on income measurement, for income measurement is the major 397 consideration of the public accountant who certifies financial statements. All accountants should be interested in the con- clusions on income measurement and cost control, since these are among the most important functions for which costs are accumulated. BIBLIOGRAPHY A. BOOKS Alford, L. P., and Russell H. Beatty. Principles pf Industrial Management. Revised edition. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1951. 779 pp. Amidon, L. Cleveland, and Theodore Lang. Essentials pf Cost Accounting. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1928. 383 pp. Anthony, Robert N. Management Accounting. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956. 511 pp. Ashton, T. S. Iron and Steel in the Industrial Revolution. Manchester, England: Manchester University Press, 1951. 265 pp. Backman, Jules. Price Practices and Price Policies. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1953. 660 pp. Bennett, S. C. and RObert Schmal. Cost Control and The Foreman. New London, Connecticut: National Foreman‘s Institute, Inc., 1952. 142 pp. Blocker, John G. Essentials pf Cost Accounting. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1942. 430 pp. Boulding, Kenneth E. Economic Analysis. Third edition. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1955. 905 pp. Brummet, R. Lee. Overhead Costing. Michigan Business Studies, Vol. XVII, No. 2, Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan, 1957. 157 pp. Camman, Eric A. Basic Standard Costs. New York: The American Institute Publishing Co., Inc., 1932. 232 pp. Carrol, Phil. How Foremen Can Control Costs. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1955. 301 pp. 399 Carson, B. Gordon (ed.). Production Hendbook. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1958. Church, A. Hamilton. Manufacturing Costs and Accounts. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., 1917. 452 pp. Church, A. Hamilton. Overhead Expense. New York: McGraw— Hill Book Co., Inc., 1930. 418 pp. Church, A. Hamilton. Production Factors. New York: The Engineering Magazine (Works Management Library). 1910. 187 pp. Clark, John Maurice. Studies in the Economics 9; Overhead Costs. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1923. 502 pp. Cost Behavior and Price Policy. A Study Prepared By The Committee on Price Determination for the Conference on Price Research. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1943. 353 pp. Davis, R. C. Industrial Organization and Management. New York: Harper and Brothers, Publishers, 1940. 636 pp. Dean, Joel. Managerial Economics. New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1951. 621 pp. Dean Joel. Statistical Cost Functions pi e Hosiery Mill. Studies in Business Administration, Vol. 11, No. 4, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1941. 116 pp. Dean, Joel. Statistical Determination pf Cost With Special Reference pp Marginal Costs. Studies in Business Administration, Vol. VII, No. 1, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1936. 145 pp. Devine, Carl T. Cost Accounting and Analysis. New York: The Macmillan Co., 1950. 752 pp. Drucker, Peter F. The Practice pf Management. New York: Harper and Brothers Publishers, 1954. 404 pp. Eggleston, DeWitt Carl. Problems ip Cost Accounting. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1918. 349 pp. 400 Ficker, Nicholas T. Industrial Cost-Finding. Factory Management Course. Volume 5. New York: Industrial Extension Institute, Inc., 1917. 511 pp. Fiske, Wyman P. and John A Beckett (eds.). Industrial Accountants' Handbook. New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1954. 1072 pp. Gantt, H. L. Organizing for Work. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and Howe, 1919. 113 pp. Garcke, Emil and J. M. Fells. Factory Accounts. Fourth and seventh editions. London: Crosby Lockwood and Son, 1893 and 1922. 264 pp. Gardner, Fred V. Profit Management and Control. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1955. 285 pp. Garner, S. Paul. Evolution pf Cost Accounting pp 1925. Tuscaloosa, Alabama: University of Alabama Press, 1954. 416 pp. Gibb, George S. The Whitesmiths pp gepnton, A History 9: Reed and Barton 1824—1943. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1943. 419 pp. Gillespie, Cecil. Cost Accounting and Control. New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1957. 824 pp. Glaeser, Martin G. Public Utilities ip American Capitalism. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1957. 624 pp. Goetz, Billy E. Managerial Planning and Control. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1949. 294 pp. Harrison, G. Charter. Standard Costs. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1930. 308 pp. - Hatfield, Henry Rand. Modern Accounting. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1909. 367 pp. Henrici, Stanley B. Standard Costs for Manufacturing. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1953. 336 pp. Jordon, J. P. and Gould L. Harris. Cost Accounting. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1920. 543 pp. 401 Keller, I. Wayne. Management Accounting for Profit. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1957. 435 pp. Knoeppel. C. E. and Edgar Seybold. Managing for Profit. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1937. 343 pp. Lawrence, F. C. and E. N. Humphreys. Marginal Costing. London: MacDonald and Evans, 1947. 117 pp. Lawrence, W. B. Cost Accounting. New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1925. 525 pp. Lawrence, W. B. Cost Accounting. Fourth edition. Revised by John Ruswinckel. New York: Prentice—Hall, Inc., 1954. 659 pp. Lewis, J. Slater. The Commercial Organization pp Factories. First edition. London: E. and F. N. Spon, 1896. 540 pp. Littleton, A C. Accounting Evolution pp 1900. New York: The American Institute Publishing Co., Inc., 1933. 368 pp. Littleton, A. C. Structure pf Accounting Theory. American Accounting Association Monograph No. 5, 1953. 234 pp. Makin, F. Bradshaw. Overhead Costs ip Theory and Practice. Second edition. London: Gee and Co., Ltd., 1949. 80 pp. Matz, Adolph, Othel J. Curry and George W. Frank. Cost Accounting. Second edition. Cincinnati, Ohio. South— Western Publishing Co., 1957. 838 pp. May, George 0. "Cost Accounting", Twenty—five Years 9; Accountipg Responsibility, 1911-1936. New York: The American Institute Publishing Co., Inc., 1936. pp. 364— 69. Moore, Franklin G. Manufacturing Management. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1953. 832 pp. Neuner, John J. W. Cost Accounting Principies and Practice. Fifth edition. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1957. 944 pp. 402 Nicholson, J. Lee and John F. Rohrbach. Cost Accounting. New York: The Ronald Press Co., 1920. 576 pp. Norton, George P. Textile Manufacturers Bookkeeping. Third edition. London: Simpkin, Marshall, Hamilton, Kent and Co., Ltd., 1894. 300 pp. Owens, Richard N. Management pp Industrial Enterprises. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1955. 669 pp. Paton, William A. and A. C. Littleton. 5p Introduction pp Corporate Accounting Standards. American Accounting Association Monograph No. 3, 1940. 156 pp. Paton, William and Russell A. Stevenson. Principles pp Accounting.- New York: The Macmillan Co., 1922. 676 pp. Sanders, Thomas Henry. Industrial Accounting. New York: McGraw—Hill Book Co., Inc., 1929. 371 pp. Schlatter, Charles F. Advanced Cost Accounting. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1939. 217 pp. Schlatter, Charles F. Elementary Cost Accounting. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1927. 321 pp. Scitovsky, Tibor. Welfare and Competition. Chicago: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1951. 457 pp. Scovell, Clinton H. Cost Accounting and Burden Application. New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1916. 328 pp. Solomons, David. "The Historical Development of Costing", David Solomons, (ed.). Studies pp Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell Limited, 1952. pp. 1-52. Sord, Burnard H., and Glenn A. Welsch. Business Budgeting, A Survey pleanagement Planning and Control Practices. New York: Controllership Foundation, Inc., 1958. 367 pp. Sowell, Ellis Mast. "The Evolution of the Theories and Techniques of Standard Costs". Unpublished Ph. D. dissertation, The University of Texas, 1944. 540 pp. 403 The Library of Factory Management. Volume V. pperations and Costs. New York: A. W. Shaw Company, 1915. 216 pp. The New International Encyclopedia. Second edition. Vol. 19, New York: Dodd, Mead and Company, 1930. Urwick, L. The Golden Book pp Management. London: Newman, Neame, Limited, 1956. 298 pp. B. PERIODICALS Adelman, M. A. "The Consistency of the Robinson-Patman Act," The Stanford Law Review, VI (December, 1953), 3-22. Adelman, M. A. "Price Discrimination As Treated in the Attorney General's Report," The University pp Pennsylvania Law Review, CIV (November, 1955), 222—242. "A Group of Letters on Direct Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV, Sec. 1. (March, 1954), 907—11. Anthony, Robert N. "Cost Concepts for Control," The Accounting Review, XXXII (April, 1957), 229—34. Avery, Harold G. "Problem of Idle Equipment," The Accounting Review, XV (December, 1940), 469—73. Bac, Alexander. "Advantages of 'Break—Even' Income Statement Compared With Convential Statement," The Journal pp Accountancy, XCI (January, 1951), 106—11. Bass, A. W. "Modern Trends in Cost Accounting," N.A.C.A. pulletin, XII, Sec. 1. (August 15, 1931), 1897—1907. Baxter, W. T. "A Note on the Allocation of Oncosts Between Departments," included in David Solomons (ed.).Studies ip Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952. 267-276. Reprinted from The Accountant, IC (November 5, 1938), 633—636. Baxter, W. T. "Should Cost Accounting Ignore Overheads?" The Accountant, CXVI (June 21, 1947), 361-2. g. .1 2“ «F‘W—W . .- ‘1 E i Z ‘. F . "! 404 Beckett, John A. "Appraisal of Direct Costing," N.A.C.A Bulletin,XXXIII, Sec. 1. (December,1951), 407—15. Beldon, J. C. "What Executives Need From Accountants," N.A.C.A. Bulletin,XII, Sec. 1. (July 15, 1931), 1823—34. Benninger, L. J. "Development of Cost Accounting Concepts and Principles," The Accounting Review, XXIX (January, 1954), 27-37. Bentley, H. C. "Problem in the Distribution of Expense Burden," The Journal pp Accountancy, XVI (July— September, 1913), 25—59, 175—209. Beyer, Robert. "Is Direct Costing The Answer," The qurnal pp Accountaney, IC (April, 1955), 45-9. Black, M. L., Jr. and Harold B. Eversole. "Cost Accounting in Price Determination," The qurnal‘pp Accountancy, LXXXII (November, 1946), 367—372. Blough,Carman G. "Comment on Direct Costing (Accounting and Auditing Problems)," The Journal pp Accountancy, IC (April, 1955), 64. Bornemann, Alfred. ”Empirical Cost Study and Economic Theory," The Accounting Review, XX (July, 1945), 327— 331. Browne, Nelson J. and Burt B. Titus. "How Much Do Indirect Expenses Vary?," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (October, 1951), 170—80. Brummet, R. Lee. "Direct Costing—~Shou1d It Be A Con- troversial Issue?," The Accounting Review, XXX (July, 1955), 439-43. Brummet, R. Lee. "Try This On Your Class Professor——A Rejoinder," The Accounting Review, XXXII (July, 1957), 480-4. Cassady, Ralph Jr. "Legal Aspects of Price Discrimination: Federal Law," The Journal pp Marketing, XI (January, 1947), 258-272. 405 Cassady, Ralph Jr. "Some Economic Aspects of Price Discrimination Under Non—Perfect Market Conditions," The Journal pp Marketing, XI (July, 1946), 7—20. Chambers, Charles R. "Conversion to Direct Costs," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (March, 1952), 791—7. Chenault, Lawrence R. "Business Behavior and the Theory of the Firm," The Accounting Review, XXIX (October, 1954), 645-651. Church, A. Hamilton. "Overhead-—The Cost of Production Preparedness," Factory and Industrial Management, CXXXI (January, 1931), 38-41. Church, A. Hamilton. "The Meaning of Commercial Organization," The Engineering Magazine, XX (December, 1900), 391—8. Church, A. Hamilton. "The Meaning of Scientific Management," The Engineering Magazine, XCI (April, 1911), 97-101. Coase, R. H. "Business Organization and the Accountant" included in David Solomons (ed.). Studies pp Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952. 105—159. Re— printed from The Accountant, IC (October-December 17, 1938), 470-2, 505—7, 537-8, 559—60, 607—8, 631—2. 665-6, 705-7, 737-9, 775—7,814—5, 834—5. Cogburn, M. B. "Burden Application," The Journal pp Accountancy, CXV (March, 1938), 208-12. Cooper, Howard E. "Some Controversial Phases of Standard Costs," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XV, Sec. 1. (September 15, 1933), 81-108. Copeland, M. A. "A Social Appraisal of Differential Pricing," The Journal pp Marketing, VI (April, 1942), 177-183. "Cost variance Gain, (Accounting Questions)," The Journal pp Accountancy, LXXII (July, 1941), 68. Cowan, David. "With Special Reference to Oncost: What it Should Include; Its Allocations and Recovery," The Accountant, XXVII (November 16, 1901), 1242-1256. 406 Darlington, P. J. "The Fundamental Principles of Works Organization'and Management," The Engineering Magezine, XXXV (April, 1908), 57—67. Dean, Joel. "Correlation Analysis of Cost Variation," The Accounting Review, XII (March, 1937), 55-60. Dean, Joel. "Methods and Potentialities of Break-Even Analysis," included in David Solomons (ed.). Studiee pp Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952. 227-266. Reprinted from The Austrialian Accountpnt, XXI (October-November, 1951), 361—71 and 1040-7. Dickinson, Sir Arthur Lowes. "The Construction Use and Abuse of Cost Accounts," The Journal pp Accountancy, XXIV (July, 1927), 1-20. Dinlocker, T. W., and A. W. Wainwright. "Idle Plant Ficilities: Separating Expense of Idleness From Manufacturing Cost," Automotive Industries, XXXXIV (May 2, 1921), 1012—7. Dohr, James L. "What They (Economists) Say About Us (Accountants)," The Journal pp Accountancy, XCVI (August, 1953), 167-75. Doyle, Leonard J. "Most Profitable Product Volume—-Taking Account of Costs and Competition," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXX, Sec. 1. (February 1, 1949), 643-52. Doyle, Leonard A. "Overhead Accounting Comes Full Circle," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV, Sec. 1. (August, 1954), 1575-85. Downie, L. W. "Normal Capacity and Its Uses," N.A,C.A. Bulletin, XXVI, Sec. 1. (September 1, 1944), 3-11. Drucker, Peter F. "Business Objectives and Survival Needs: Notes On a Discipline of Business Enterprise," The Journal pp Business, XXXI (April, 1958), 81-90. Dugdale, Harry. "Management Accounting: Segregation of Overhead," The Accountants Journal, (England), XLVV (May, 1955), 163-4. 407 Earley, James S. “Recent Developments in Cost Accounting and the 'Marginal Analysis'? The Journal pp Political Economy, LXIII (June, 1955), 227—42. Editorial. "Cost Accounts," The Accountant, XXXII (June 17, 1905), 727-29. Edwards, James Don. "This New Costing Concept—-Direct Costing?," The Accounting Review, XXXIII (October, 1958), 561-67. Edwards, Ronald S. "Some Notes On the Early Literature and Development of Cost Accounting in Great Britain,".Ihe .Accountant, XCVII (August 7 - September 11, 1937), 193—5, 225-31, 253-5, 283-7, 313-6, 343-4. Eiteman, Wilford J. "Factors Determining the Location of the Least Cost Point," The American Economic Review, XXXVIII (December, 1947), 910-18. Eiteman, Wilford J. "The Equilibrium of the Firm in Multi- Process Industries," The Qparterly Journal pp Ecpnomics, LIX (February, 1945), 280-6. Eiteman, Wilford J. "The Least Cost Point, Capacity, and Marginal Analysis," The American Economic Review, XXXVIII (December, 1948), 899—904. Emerson, Harrington. "Efficiency As A Basis for Operation and Wages--Part IV. The Modern Theory of Cost Accounting," The gpgineering Magazine, XXXVI (December, 1908), 336-346. Fiske, Wyman P. "Accounting for Unused Facilities," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XIII, Sec. 1. (November 15, 1931), 355-69. Fitch, Stanley G. H. "Deflation in Relation to Cost Accounting," Tpe Journal pp Accountancy, XXXIII (January, 1922), 1-11. Fitch, Stanley G. H. "Present Day Problems in Industrial Accounting," The Journal pp_Apcountancy, XXIV (July, 1922), 1-10. Frank, George W. "Will Direct Costing Theory Stand Inspection," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIV, Sec. 1. (December, 1952), 490-9. 408 Franklin, B. A. "Cost Methods That Give the Executive Control of His Business,“ The Engineering Magazine, XLII-XLIII (January-July, 1912), 577-85, 921-27, 48-56, 192-97, 421-33, 560-66. Franklin, W. H. "Allocation of Overhead Costs--A Short Cut," N.A.C.A; Bulletin, XXXII, Sec. 1. (August, 1951), 1527-36. Freer, Robert E. "Accounting Problems Under the Robinson- Patman Act," The Journal pp Accountancy, LXV (June, 1938), 480-7. Gantt, H. L. "The Basis of Manufacturing Costs," Industrial Management, LIII (June, 1917), 369-70. Gardner, Fred V. "Variable Budget in Management by Exception," pactory Management and Maintenance, XCV (November-December, 1937), 67—74, 64—74. Garry, H. S. "Factory Costs," The Ageguntant, XXIX (July 25, 1903), 954-61. George, Eéwin B. "The Robinson-Patman Act Begins to Acquire Meaning,” Dun's Review, XLVIII (March, 1940), 20-28. Goetz, Billy E. "Tomorrow's Cost System," included in William E. Thomas. Readings pp Cost Accounting, Budgeting, and Control. Cincinnati: South-Western Publishing Co., 1955. 67-80. Reprinted from Advanced Management, XII (December, 1947), 172-8. Goliger, Josef. "Fixed Charges and Profit," The Accounting Review, XXV (October, 1950), 412-16. Gordon, R. A. "Short-Period Price Determination in Theory and Practice," The American Economic Review, XXXVIII (June, 1948), 265-288. Green, E. A. "Practical Standards--Their Development and Use," N.A.C.A; Bulletin, XVI, Sec. 1. (February 1, 1935), 641—56. Greer, Howard C. "Alternatives to Direct Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin! XXXV, Sec. 1. (March, 1954), 878-88. 409 Greer, Howard. "Cost Factors in Price—Making," The Harvard Business Review, XXX (July—August, 1952), 33-45. Greer, Howard. "Differences in Cost as a Basis for Price Differentialsfl The Journal pp Accountanpy, LXIII (April, 1937), 255-66. Grover, Albert E. "Some Important Points in Burden Dis- tribution," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XII Sec. 1. (September 1, 1930), 1653-68. Haines, W. W. "Capacity Production and the Least Cost Point," The American Economic Review, XXXVIII (September, l948),617-24. Hanson, O. E. "Depreciation Is A Period Cost—-Practica11y Speaking," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV, Sec. 1. (May, 1954), 1182-5. Harris, Jonathan N. "Case Against Administrative Expenses," Thngournap_pp Accountancy, LXXXII (July, 1916), 32-6. Harris, Jonathan N. "The Author Replies," N.A.C.A. Bnlletin, XVII, Sec. 1. (March 15, 1936), 755-59. Harris, Jonathan N. "What Did We Earn Last Month?," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XVII, Sec. 1. (January 15, 1936), 501-26. Harrison, G Charter. "Bugbear of Burden Distribution, A Plan to Eliminate its Work and Worry," Management and Administratipn, VI (July, 1923), 49-54. Harrison, G. Charter. "Cost Accounting in the New Industrial Day," Industrial Management, LVIII—LIX (December, 1918- January, 1919), 441-4, 13-7. Harrison, G. Charter. "Cost Accounting to Aid Production," Industrial Management, (October, 1918-June, 1919), 273-82, 391-8, 456-63, 49-55, 131-9, 218-24, 314-18, 400-4, 483-7. Harrison, G. Charter. "Scientific Basis for Cost Accounting," Industrial Management, LIX (March, 1920), 237-42. Harrison, G. Charter. "Standard Costs as an Element of Managerial Technique," Bulletin pp the Taylor Society, l 410 XVII (April, 1932), 57-62. Harrison, G. Charter. ”The Practical Economist's Profit and Loss Statement,” N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXX, Sec. 1. (December 15, 1948), 443-56. $ Harrison, G. Charter. "Working Plans for Standard Costs," Management Engineering, III (June—December, 1922), 331-6, 5-10, 97-101, 161-6, 227-31, 289—94, 353-7. Harrison, W. E. "Marginal Costing; A New Tool for Management," The Accountant, CXXXII (June 25, 1955), 716-23. Hartogensis, Alwyn M. "The Art and Practice of Pricing," N.A.C.A. Bulietin, XXXIX, Sec. 1. (March, 1958), 63-74. Hattersley, G. Stanley. "Costing," The Accountant, LXIV (May 28, 1921), 681-86. Heckert, J. Brooks. "Coverage and Cost Provisions of the Robinson-Patman Act," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXX, Sec. 1. (March 1, 1949), 269-82. Hepworth, Samuel R. "Direct Costing--The Case Against," The Accounting Review, XXIX (January, 1954), 94—9. Hosick, Ted R. "Effect of Direct Costing on Asset Accounting, Income Reporting," ppp gpurnal pp Accountancy, XCVII (October, 1953), 444-8. Hovey, Floyd F., and C. E. K. Mees. "Cost Control With Fluctuating Production; A Description of a Definite System for Making Up Cost Control Sheets Under Fluctuating Production," Bulletin pp the Taylor Society, XIV (August, 1929), 160-7. Jackson, J. Hugh "Quarter-Century of Cost Accounting Pro- gress," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXVIII, Sec. 1. (June 1, 1947), 1201-9. Kemp, William S. "Budgets and Predetermination of Costs," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, VII, Sec. 1. (July 15, 1926), 817—827. Kennedy, Donald D. "Variability of Overhead Costs," The gpppnal pp Accountancy, XLIX (March, 1930), 202-12. 411 Kent, William. "New Method of Determining Factory Costs," The Iron Age, XCVIII (August 24, 1916), 392-4. Klein, Frank. "Some Developments in Variable Budgeting," ,N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XVII, Sec. 1. (June 1, 1936), 1155-71. Knapp. C. Howard. "How to Determine Costs on Pre-determined Sales Forecasts With Special Reference to Idle Capacity Costs Applied To the Product," E.A.C.A Bulletin, XIV, Sec. 1. (February 15, 1933), 901-30. Knoeppel. F. J. "Fundamentals of Accounting for Industrial Waste," The Journal pp Accountancy, XXV (May, 1918), 351-59. Kohl, Clem N. "What is Wrong with Most Profit and Loss Statements?,” N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XVIII, Sec. 1. (July 1, 1937), 1207—19. Kramer, Philip. "Selling Overhead to Inventory," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXVIII, Sec. 1. (January 15, 1947), 587-603. Lang, Theodore. "Concepts of Cost, Past and Present," N.ALC.A. Bulletin, XXVIII, Sec. 1. (July 15, 1947), 1377-90. Lawrence, W. B. "Weaknesses in Standard Costs," N.A.C.A Bulletin, XI, Sec. 1. (July 15, 1930), 1493-17305. Lemke, B. C. "Is Manufacturing Cost an Objective Concept?," The Accounting Review, XXVI (January, 1951), 77-9. Ludwig, John W. "Inaccuracies of Direct Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV, Sec. 1. (March, 1954), 895-906. Luenstroth, H. W. "Case for Direct Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (August, 1952), 1479-95. McAnly, H. T. "Should Unusual Costs Be Allocated to Period Rather Than Product?," The Journal pp Accountancy, LXXXIII (May, 1947), 426-35. McEachren, John W. "Can Standard CosfisBe Standardized?," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXI, Sec. 1. (February 1, 1940), 681-92. I 412 McHenry, William B. "Is Your Cost System Scientific," The Engineering Magazine, LI (August, 1916), 678-86. Machlup, Fritz. "Marginal Analysis and Empirical Research," The American Economic Review, XXXVI (September, 1946), 519-54. March, James H. "Applying Burden by Production Factors," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (April, 1952), 911-20. Marple, Raymond P. "Direct Costing and the Uses of Cost Data," The Accounting Review, XXX (July, 1955), 430-8. Marple, Raymond P. "Try This on Your Class Professor," The Accounting Review, XXXI (July, 1956), 492-97. Mauriello, Joseph A. "Convertibility of Direct and Conventional Costing," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXV, Sec. 1. (March, 1954), 888-94. Moss, Morton F. and Wilber C. Haseman. "Some Comments On The Applicability of Direct Costing To Decision Making," TanAccounting Review, XXXII (April, 1957), 184-93. Murdock, Andrew A. "The Proper Treatment of Machine Costs-- A Criticism and a Theory," The Journal pp Accountaney, III (December, 1906), 123-30. Myers, J. H. "Standards for Manufacturing Expense," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XIX, Sec. 1. (November 15, 1937), 318-29. Neikirk, Waldo W. "How Direct Costing Can Work for Manage— ment,",N.A.C.A. Belletin, XXXII, Sec. 1. (January, 1951), 523-35. Nickerson, Clarence B. "Cost Control--A Review of Techniques," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXIX, Sec. 1. (July 15, 1948), 1399- 1408. Nielsen, Oswald. "Direct Costing--The Case 'For'," The Accounting Review, XXIX (January, 1954), 89—93. Norris, Harry. "Overhead Costs," The Accountant, CXVI (January 18, 1947), 35-7. 413 Noyes, C. Reinhold. "Certain Problems in the Empirical Study of Costs," The American Economic Review, XXXI (September, 1941), 473-92. Oliver, H. M., Jr. "Marginal Theory and Business Behavior," The American Economic Review, XXXVII (June, 1947), 375-83. , Palmer, J. L. "Production Budgeting,” EAA.C.A. Bulletin, VII, Sec. 1. (October 15, 1925), 98-103. Patrick, A. W. "Some Observations on the Break-Even Chart," The Accounting Review, XXXIII (October, 1958), 573-80. Pedder, 8. "Cost Accounts: their Advantages and their Relation to Business Results," The Accountant, XXXII (April 29, 1905), 518-30. Pinkerton, Paul W. "Step—by-Step Approach to the Pre— determination of Profit at Varying Volumes,” N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XVI, Sec. 1. (March 1, 1935), 754-76. "Pricing Techniques and Practices Today: A Survey," The Management Review, XLVI (May, 1957), 8-9. Prochazka, George A. "Controlling Costs by Their Variations," Industrial Management, LXXIII (January-March, 1927), 10-15, 117-22, 147-50. Raff, R. J. "Accounting for Profits—-Cost Control of Sales Volume and Profit," The Accountant, CXXVIII (February 7, 1953), 146-8. Rahl, James A. "Antitrust Policy in Distribution," The University pp Pennsylvania Law Review, CIV (November, 1955), 185-221. Raun, Donald L. “Problem of Fixed Charges," The Accounting Review, XXVI (July, 1951), 338-46. Rautenstrauch, Walter. ‘"Economic Characteristics of the Manufacturing Industries," Mechanical Engineering, LIV (November, 1932), 759-70. Reder, M. W. "A Reconsideration of the Marginal Productivity Theory,“ The Journal pp Political Economy, XL 414 (October, 1947), 450-58. Rowe, Frederick M. "Price Differentials and Product Differentiatiation: The Issues Under the Robinson- Patman Act,“ The Yale Law Journal, LXVI (November, 1956), 1-49. Sapega, Andrew S. "More Useful Accounting for Indirect Costs," NpA.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (September, 1951), 13-25. Schlatter, Charles F. "Fixed Expense," The Accounting Review, XX (April, 1945), 156-63. Scholefield. J. R. "RObinson-Patman Act and the Accountant,” The Journal pp Apcountancy, LXIV (July, 1937), 16-73. Scovell, Clinton Homer. "Cost Accounting Practice With Special Reference to the Machine-Hour Rate," ppe pournal pp Accountancy, XVII (January, 1914), 13-27. Seidman, J. 3. "Do We Mistreat Administrative Expenses in Inventory?," The Journal pp Accountancy, LXXXI (April, 1946), 286—8. Seiler, Robert E. "Improvements in External Reporting by Use of Direct Costing," The Accounting Review, XXXIV (January, 1959), 59-66. Smith, Caleb. ”The Cost—Output Relation for U. 8. Steel Corporation," The Review pp Economic Statistics, XXIV (November, 1942), 166-76. Smith, Gershom. "Distribution of Indirect Costs By the Machine-Hour Method," The Engineering Magazine, XXXVII (June, 1909), 384-94. Solomons, David. "Cost Accounting and the Use of Space and Equipment,“ included in David Solomons (ed.). Studies pp Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell Ltd., 1952. 277-91. Reprinted from The Accountant (March 27- April 3, 1948), 240-1, 260-3.) Staehle, Hans, "The Measurement of Statistical Cost Functions: An Appraisal of Recent Contributions," The American Economic Review, XXXII (June, 1942), 320-33. 415 Steele, F. R. Carnegie. "Significant Developments in American Industry and Accounting," The Journal pp Accountancy, XLIII (January, 1927), 20-32. Stigler, G. J. "Production and Distribution in the Short- Run," The Journap pp Political Economy, XLVII (June, 1939), 305-27. Stock, A. F. and J. M. Coffey. "Overhead During Low Volume.Production," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, VI, Sec. 1. (February 16, 1925), 11 pp. Straus, Everet. "Cost Accounting and Statistical Cost Functions," The American Economic Review, XXXV (June, 1945), 430-31. Taggart, Herbert F. “Cost Justification Under the Robinson— Patman Act," The Journal pp Accountancy, CI (June, 1956), 52-6. Taggart, Herbert F. "The Standard Brands Case," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXI, Sec. 1. (October 15, 1939), 195-262. Thorp, Willard L. "Price Discrimination and Cost,” ppp Journal pp Accountancy, LXIII (March, 1937), 183-6. Torian, Thomas R. "Measuring Activity and Capacity for the Budget," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 1. (October, 1951), 156—67. Ullrich, William A. "Manufacturing Expense Analysis, Classification, and Distribution," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XI, Sec. 1. (December 1, 1929), 397-418. Uerk. L. "Cost Accounting and Management," The Cost Accountant, XI (April, 1934), 327—35. Vatter, William J. "Accounting Measurements of Incremental Costs," The Journal pp Business, XVIII (July, 1945), 145-56. Vatter, William J. "Cost Accounting and Statistical Cost Functions," The American Economic Review, XXXV (December, 1945), 940-42. 416 Vatter, William J. “Limitations of Overhead Allocation," The Accounting Review, XX (April, 1945), 163-76. White, Ben C. "What is Overhead?," The Journal pp Accountancy, LXXIX (June, 1945), 445-50. Whitmore, John. "Factory Accounting As Applied to Machine Shops," The Journal pp Accountancy, II-III (August, 1906— January, 1907), 248—58, 345-57, 430-41, 20-31, 106-14, 211-18. Whitmore, John. ”Shoe Factory Cost Accounts," The Journal pp Accountanpy, VI (May, 1908), 12-25. Whittaker, Edmund. "Realism and Cost Accounting," The Accounting Review, XXI (January, 1946), 13—19. Wilks, Paul A. "Flexible Budget System at Strathmore Paper Company," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XVII, Sec. 1. (June 1, 1936), 1143—55. Williams, C. B. "Treatment of Costs During Periods of Varying Volumes of Production," The Journal pp Accountancy, XXXII (November, 1921), 329—33. Williams, C. B. ”Treatment of Overhead When Production is Below Normal," The Journal pp Accountancy, XXXI (May, 1921), 336-42. Wolfe, Frank B. "Providing a Check on Unused Productive Capacity; Accounting for the Cost of Idle Plant," Industrial Management, LXXIV (November, 1927), 305-9. Wyer, Rolfe. "Replacing the Myth of Fixed and Variable Costs," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXVIII, Sec. 1. (November, 1956), 353-61. C. PROCEEDINGS, REPORTS AND MISCELLANEOUS PAPERS Advisory Committee on Cost Justification. Report pp The Federal Trade Commission. Washington; Government Printing Office, February, 1956. 417 Alden, William H. "Handling the Expense of Idle Time," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Xearbook, 1924, 115-20. Armstrong, W. C. "In Establishing The Budget For Burden, Shall 'Normal' Capacity Be Set For Each Department by (1) Giving Due Regard To The Capacities of Related Departments; or (2) Without Regard to Other Depart— ments; or (3) With All Departments Set At The Same Arbitrary Level?," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1930, 172-4. Aronson, A. S. "Defenses under the Robinson—Patman Act with Special Reference to Cost Defenses," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1937, 27-46. Black, Martin L., and Harold B. Eversole. A Report pp Cost Accounting pp Industry, Accounting Department, Office of Price Administration, Washington: Government Printing Office, June, 1946. Breitenbucher, Verne. "Putting Cost Accounting to Work—— For Cost Control," National Association pp post Accountants' Yearbook, 1946, 96-113. Camman, Eric A. "Uses of Standard Costs," flational Aesociation pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1926, 103-144. Castenholz, William B. "The Application of Selling and Auministrative Expense To Product," National Association pp Cost Accountants Yearbook, 1922, 121-54. Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards of The American Accounting Association. "Report of the Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards," The Accounting Review, XXVII (April, 1952), 174-88. Committee on Cost Concepts and Standards of the American Accounting Association, "Tentative Statement of Cost Concepts Underlying Reports for Management Purposes," The Accounting Review, XXXI (April, 1956), 182-93. Cooper, Howard E. "Elimination of Fixed Overhead Expense From Inventory and Production Costs Under the Standard Cost Plan," fiational Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1936, 310-21. 418 Cornell, C. H. ”How is Over-or-Under—Absorbed Burden To Be Applied With Regard to Inventory at the End of the Fiscal Year?," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1930, 194-8. Discussion. "Some Debatable Points in Cost Accounting Theory," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1924. 229-72. Discussion. "Some Debatable Points in Cost Accounting," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1925, 157-205. Duncan, W. L., Jr. "Modern Management Control of Factory Costs," Organizing for Improved Production and Cosp pontrol, American Management Association Manufacturing Series, No. 202. Papers presented at the April, 1952 Manufacturing Conference of The American Management Association, 1952, 9-15. Edwards, Corwin D. "Types of Differential Pricing,” ppp Journal pp Marketing, VI, Part II, Papers presented at the American Marketing Association Semi-Annual Meeting, December, 1941, 156-65. Edwards, R. S. "The Rationale of Cost Accounting," included in David Solomons (ed.L Studies pp Costing. London: Sweet and Maxwell, Ltd., 1952. 87-104. A lecture delivered at the London School of Economics and Political Science on February 8, 1937. Eiteman, Wilford J. Price Determination--Business Practice Versus Economic Theory. Bureau of Business Research Report Number 16. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan, 1949. 39 pp. - Fordham, Thomas B. "Deficiencies of Cost Accounting And Their Cure, From the Standpoint of The Manufacturer," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1924, 81-9. Fowler, George L. "Estimating The Cost of Foundry Work," Transactions pp ppp American Society pp Mechanical Engineers, IX (May, 1888 Meeting). 390-97. 419 Gantt, H. L. "Influence of Executives,"Anpals pp ppp American Academy pp gplitical and Social Science, LXXXV (September, 1919), 257-63. Gantt, H. L. "The Effect of Idle Time on Costs and Profits," Annals pp the American Academy pp Political and Social Science, LXI (September, 1915), 86—89. Gantt, H. L. "The Relation Between Production and Costs," Transactions pp the American Socpppy pp Methanicel Engineers, XXXVII (June, 1915 Meeting). 109-28. Gardner, Fred V. "The New Meaning of Break-Even Points," Production Costs and Breakeven Pointsy American Management Association Production Series No. 177. Papers presented at the December 1947 Production Conference of the American Management Association, 1948, 3—32. Glasner, J. B. "In Establishing The Budget for Burden Shall Consideration be Given To The Relation Between The Sales of The Industry As a Whole and The Productive Capacity Of The Whole Industry; Or Shall Consideration Be Restricted To These Facts For The Company Itself,“ National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1930, 179-86. Hall, R. L. and C. J. Hitch. "Price Theory and Business Behavior," prord Economic Papers pp. 2, (May, 1939), 12-45. ' Harrison, G. Charter. "Some Fundamental Defects in Cost Accounting," National Association pp Cost Accountants' .Yearbogk. 1924, 72-80. Harrison, G. Charter. "Standard Costs and Variations,” National Apsociation pp Cost Apcountants' YearbOOk, 1925, 109-36. Hearings Before the House Judiciary Committee on Bills to Amend The Clayton Act, 74th Congress, lst Session (1935). How Standard Costs Are Being Used Currently. New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1950. (Complete N.A.C.A. Standard Cost Research Series). 420 James, Charles C. "Capacity,Costs and Prices," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, p945, 39-48. Knapp. C. Howard. "Variations from Predetermined Standards of Burden in Manufacturing Costs," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbopp, 1924: 206-19. Lane, H. M. "A Method of Shop Accounting To Determine ShOp Cost and Minimum Selling Price," Transactions pp ppe American §pciety pp Mechanical Engineers, XVIII (May, 1897 Meeting), 892-900. Langenburg, William. "Cost Reduction Activity at Johnson and Johnson-—Cost Accounting--Basis for Management Action," Company Experience pp Aanufacturing Cost Reduction, American Management Association Manu- facturing Series, No. 224. Papers presented at the March 1956 Manufacturing Conference of the American— Management Association, 1956, 8-16. McAnly, H. T. "Putting Cost Accounting to Work-—For Profit Determination and Inventory Valuation," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1946, 131-42. March, J. H. "In Establishing the Budget For Burden Shall 'Normal' Capacity Be Set For Each Department by (1) Giving Due Regard To The Capacities of Related Departments: of (2) Without Regard To Other Departments; of (3) With All Departments Set At the Same Arbitrary Level?," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1930, 174-79. N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 7. "The Uses and Classifications of Cost," NAA.C.A. Bulletin, XXVII, Sec. 2. (May 15, 1946), 939-52. IN.A“C.A. Research Series No. 16. "Variations of Costs With VOlume," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXX, Sec. 3. (June 15, 1949), 1215-37. N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 17. "Analysis of Cost-- Volume--Profit--Re1ationships," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXI, Sec. 3. (December, 1949), 523-63. 421 N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 18. "The VOlume Factor in Budgeting Costs," N.A.C.A. Bulletin, XXXI, Sec. 3. (June, 1950), 1295—1314. N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 22. "The Analysis of Cost Variances," N.A.C.A. Aulletin, XXXIII, Sec. 2. (August, 1952), 1547-82. N.A.C.A. Research Series No. 23. "Direct Costing," N.A.C.A pulletin, XXXIV, Sec. 3, (April, 1953), 1079-1128. N.A.C.A. Research Study. "Accounting for Excess Labor Costs and Overhead Under Conditions of Increased Production," ALA.C.A. Bulletin, XXII, Sec. 3.(August 15, 1941), 1551-70. N.A.C.A. Research Study. "Practice in Applying Overhead and Calculating Normal Capacity," N.A.CpA. Bulletin, XIX, Sec. 3. (April 1, 1938), 917-34. Nourse, Edwin G. "Cost Finding and Price Determination," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, Nourse,Edwin G. "Practical Capacity vs. Normal Capacity," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1945, 48-54. Reitell, Charles. "Standard Cost Plan for Naca Company," ‘gational Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1931, 14-35. Report pp the Attorney General's National Committee pp Study The Antitrust Laws. Washington: Government Printing Office, March, 1955. "Report of the Special Committee on Interest in Relation to Cost," The American Institute pp Accountants, 1918 .Xearbook, 110-12. Rush, Edward P. "In Establishing The Budget For Burden, Shall Normal Capacity Be Set To Allow Only For Operating Interruptions, Thus Giving A Normal Which Is The Maximum Just Possible of Attainment; Or Shall It Allow For Unused Capacity Due To Insufficient Sales Demand, 422 Thus Giving A Maximum Which May Probably Be Obtained," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, p930, 167—71. Stamp, James H. "Cost Reduction Activity at Johnson and Johnson--Cost Reduction Through Management," Company Experiences pp Cost Reduction, American Management Association Manufacturing Series, No. 221. Papers presented at the March 1956 Manufacturing Conference of the American Management Association, 1956, 3—8. "Standard Costs--How To Use Them, Standard Costs—-How To Get Them," fiational Association pp Cost Accountants' Yearbook, 1926, 97-194. Thorp, Williard L. "Accounting for the Robinson-Patman Act," National Association pp Cost Accountants' Xearbook, 1937, 6-27. phiform Accounting Manual for the Electrical Manufacturing Industry. Seventh edition. New York: National Electrical Manufacturers Association, 1949. Woodley, C. A. "Organizing for Efficient Production and Effective Cost Control," peg Controls for Fixed and variable Costs. American Management Association Production Series, No. 178. Papers presented at the March, 1948 Production Conference of the American Management Association, 1948, 3-13. Yntema, Theodore, Chairman. "Round Table on Cost Functions and Their Relation to Imperfect Competition," Papers and Proceedings of the 52nd Annual Meeting of the American Economics Association Philadelphia, December, 1939. pnp American Economic Review, XXX, Part 2, (March, 1940), 400-02. w... 6 "~84” \'M 1 1:;r'. . . f“ ‘ L ‘1 ." . ‘ §" qr: £3: a \