waxy um: mews: 5:: m2 amass»: :zm’mcz-u‘é‘m? mm x: u CM" VALE": camum Thasis t‘ur #53 Degree :1? fiE. 31. 5E! ECEEKGAN‘ STA”? Ll V‘f‘E" "E" Ear net: 35;”. “‘6' 65"" IE "3 Pal I??? LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5/08 KzlProleocaPros/CIRCIDaIeDue.indd ECONOMIC ANALYSIS or *mumm INPUT-OUTPUT DATA FROM THE CAUGA VALLEY, COLOIBIA 13! HERNAE‘I BERTOLDTTO AH ABSTRACT Subnltted to the College or Agrloulturo of Michigan State University or Agriculturo and Applied Science in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE Dam-hunt. of Agricultural Economic. 1909 APPROVED Bartolotto 1 ABSTRACT Current fertilizer recommendations generally reflect inadequate attention to economic considerations. Farmers are being eupplied with fertilizer information free which, implicitly or eXplicitly, the conclusion is being drewn that the moat adequate level of fertilization ie the one at which maximm yield: per acre are attained, m ie eeldom consistent with the more important concern of maximizing profite. Profits are increased only so long no the cost of adding fertilizer inpute ie leee tinn the added return derived. from their uee. The experimental work to determine fertilizer input- ercp output reletionehipe and to provide information for making more dependable recommendation to farmers eat ecndncted emperetivelr by the Colombia Project of Michigan Btete Univereity, the Feeulted de Agronomic of the Univerei- ded-flecicnel de colon'bie. at Pnlnire. (colonize) and e dole-mien farmer. Bencr Edgardo Patina. during 1957. the We studied ere corn and beene. The variable nutriente etudied ere nitrogen, phosphoroue and poteeeiun. ‘i'he enelyeie of the date produced by theee experimente penite more adequate analysis of fertilization retee and of the recommendation which are given to farmere. Bertolottc 2 The analyeie of theee'data are based on the. concept of a continuous mathematical production function. Yield reepcneee to different fertilizer nutriente are dependent upon the levele of the variable nutrient inpute. The economic Optima are determined where the marginal value productiv1ty of a nutrient input ie equal to the coat of adding another unit of such input of fertilizer. m two-variable functicne were fitted to the experimental data for corn Patino Lower and corn Patina Upper Field. After applying varioue etatietical teete it vae decided that a eroee product production function of the fonu ’ Ye=a§bN§cP§dN3§ePz+fNP where to in yield and H and P are per acre applicatione of nitrogen and phoephoric acid nae coneidered a better repreeentation of the functional relationahipe involved tmn a square root equation which was the alternative pruduetion function fitted to the data. For eornPatino Lower Field data, nitrogen wee found to exert the predominant influence on yield, even though reeponee wae aleo obtained from the applicatione of phoephoric acid. For corn Patino Upper Field data , only phosphoric acid Bertolbttc 3 applications were found to influence yield. three three-variable functions were fitted to the emerinental data for bean Patina 1957/58. After applying statistical teete a Cobb-Douglas function of the fern: Ivan considered a more appropriate fit for thie eat of experimental data, firm the square root and oroee product production functions the alternative equations fitted to the data. The economic Optima conditione are based both in the phyeical functional relationshipe and in the price con- ditions for fertilizer inputs and product output existim at a given moment. If the price relationships involved change, a new optimun amount of fertilizer inputs and nutrient conbinatione to apply become profitable as determined by the new nutrient-crop price ratio existing after the change. Ii‘hie study shows that further emperinental work in corn, beans and other crepe ie needed in the Canon Valley. the eXperieental design used in this study has proved ueeful to obtain the kind of eXperinental data needed to make sound recommendatione to farmers. In view of present agricultural development projects Bertolette 4 under way in Colombia,-thie kind of reeearch.work may be the beat any to promote an efficient reallocation of resources and can make an important contribution to increased.productive capacity or the Colombian agriculture. Em;fibf‘ilc AERLYGIZB 1!»? F 3563.11.11.23qu INPUTUCUTPU? DATA F335 THE CAUCA VAZLEY, CCLOEHSIA 8:! me ammw no A THESIS Submitted to the (bums of Agricultur- of Hicnignn State! University of Agriculture and Applied Bcianoc in partial fulfillment of the requirmcmtc for the degree of HASTER U? HGIPNGE Departnmt of Agricultural Economics 1959 11 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The author wishee to eXpreee his appreciation to Dr. Glenn L. Johnson, major professor, for his counsel, guidance and for constant encouragement throughout thie _ etudy and during the whole or the author's graduate work. The author in particularly indebted to International Cooperation Adminietreticn (1.0.A.) or waehington, D. 0., and to ite Mieeicn to Chile. for providing the echolarehdp which enabled graduate work to be undertaken at Michigan State University. thanks areleleo due to the Catholic‘Univereity (Chile) tcr’granting the necessary leave to study in the United Statee. The author ie aleo indebted to Dr. Leonard Kyle who reed the manuecript and.provided valuable euggeeticne and conetructive criticiee. Thanke are given to Bernard Hoffnar and to the pereonnel or the etatietical pool for carrying out a major portion or the computatione. 111 TABLE 0? CONT}: T3 Page ACKHUELEDGWEflTS e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e 11 LIST OF TABLES e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e 7 LIST 0? FIGURES e e e e e e e e o e e e e e e e e e e V11 can-mm 1 THE IETUWZEZATIOUSFM3 OF Aflfifflififilc AN?) ECUHUHIC C(JI-Scm’TS In r‘mTILIzm RZSJEMECH . . 1 The Type of Information Hooded by Farmers 000 e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e 1 Economic-Agronomic Integration in Fertilizer Research e e e e e e e e e e e 4 2 THE TE‘QTX‘JHE Ami) LOGICAL FC‘UHIFLTION OF PfiODUCTIUB FUNCTION ANALYQIS e e e e e e e e 7 The Production Function in Fertilizer RBBBRPOD e e e e e e e e O D e e e e e e 7 The Concept of Eaximizetion . . . . . . . 7 3 BfiflTIBTXCAL REASUEEHEflTB e e e e e e e e e e 10 Introduction I e e e e e e e e e e e e e 10 Graphic Analysis of Functional Relationships e e e e e e e e e e e e e‘e 11 THE Estimating Equation e e e e e e e o e 11 The Standard Error of Estimate. . . . . . 13 heaeurement 0: Correlation. e e e e e e e 15 Variation EXpleinod e The Coefficient of Determination. e I e e e I e e e e e e 16 The Coefficient of correlation. e . . . . 17 Tests of Correlation Results. . . . . . . 19 (a) the Validity teste e e e e e e e 19 (b) thfi ”Elifiblllty tQSt e e e e e e B 4 KC3I'LTKIFEI‘IIiTlsL WCRK AND WHJRCE CF DfsTA . e e e 23 Th3 Corn Data 9 e e e e e e e e e e e e e 23 Th6 BB£H Data 0 e e e e e e e e e e e e e 24 com-m 5 DERIVnW 10% :F PRODUCTIUH IUHLiIOWS FROM XIELD DATA e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e Production Functions Fitted to fiata . . . Previous hyperinontal lleeulte U.' =.ing these Nationfie e e e e e e e e e e e e (a) nouare hoot Production Function. ('0) {moss Product Prozluotion Function e e e o e e e e e e e e (o) Cobtrbouglae Pmrluotion Function e e e e n e e e e e e e Chooeing the "3.331;" Fitting Function. 9 e Analysis Of the Data. e e e e e e e e 0 Analysis of the Patina Lower Field Corn Data e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e (a aquaro float Production ?unotion. (13 Cross Product Production » Function e e e I e e e e e Frofiuotion Surface Estimates. 1 e e IEoonomio Ohtima o e e e e e e e e Analysis of the Patino Upper Field Corn note e e e e e o e e e e e c e e e e (a) Square hoot Production Function. (b) Cross Product Production Function e e e e e e o e e Production Surface EStlmatfifle e o e Economic option 9 e e e e e e e e e Analysis or the Patino Boone Date ‘ . 1957/58 e e e e e e e e e e e e o e e e e (a) Square Root.Produotion Funotion. (b) Cross Product Production Function e e e e e 9 e e o e e e (o) Cobh~noug1ae Production Function e e e e o e e e e e e e P’DdUGtian Surface ES‘lmatflae 9 e e e e e Eoonomic Optima o e e e I e e e e e e e e I b e a o I I I O C 0. CI 0 O. C 6 EVALUATIGH MED CUflCLUSIOHB‘ . . .in g g . . . _. arr own A ?nrinnoe e e e e e e e e e e u e e e e e Validity of Experimental Reeulto Over Time e e e e e e e e e e e e e e COHOIUS1038 o q n e e e e e e e e e e Implicatione. e e e e e e e o e e i e t I C. O C i U l O 0' I g I O I O D I I O O ~§ .0. BIBLIQGW’EY!Q.DICIQQ6......IIOGI iv TABLE LIST OF TAELHS Levels of Fertilization for the Corn ExPorimonts, Patina Lower and Patina UFDBP Fifilde 1957e I e e e e e e e e e e e e Experimentnl Design of the Corn Experimente Patina Lower and retina Uppfir FIB-Id, 1957e e e e e e e e e e e e e e Levels of fertilization for the Beans Experiment, Patino, 1957/53e e e o e n e e e Experimentnl Design of the Boone Experiment, Patina, 1957/58e e e e e e e e e nines or “n“ and “213* for Two Variablo nutrients and voluee or “t“ for Individual Regression Coefficients, tor‘Petino Lower PieldCornlmtn.u...e........ Total Calculated Corn Kielde from opeoified Rates of Application of Nitrogen and Phoephoric Acid, Predioted from the Cross Product Equation, ror’Patino Loner Field Corn Data, 1957 y e e e u e e e e e e e e e Total Predicted and Cbeerted‘Yieldo ’0? Corn Patina LOWS? Flfild. 1957e e e e e e iarginal rrodnctivitiee of Nitrogen and Phosphoric Acid in the Production of Corn for Inputs Indicated (Nitrogen at TOP of Enoh.Pnir and Phosphoric Acid at Bottom} tor'Patino Lower Field Corn Date, 1957 . . e Veluoe of “h“ and “R3' tor*Two Variable Hotriente and Values of “t“ for Individual Regression Coefficients, for Pntino Upper Field Corn Date, 1957 . . . . . Page 49 64 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 Total Calculated Corn Yields from opeoified Katee of Arplicntion of nitrogen and Phosphoric Acid, Predicted from the Croce Froouot Function for Patino Upper Field Corn Date, 195? . . . Total Predicted and Observed X1olds for GOP“ 9ntino Upper F1615 Data, 195? c e e e e Harginal Productivitiee or nitrogen and Phosphoric Acid in the Production of Corn for Inputs Indicated (nitrogen at TOp of Each Fair and Phoepmric Acid at Bottom) for Patina Upper Field Yield Data, 1957 I e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e 9 Values of “R“ and ‘32., for Three Variable nutrients and Values of 't‘ for Indiriduol Regression coefficients, tOr'PfitinO Bean Data, 1957/53e e e e e e e e Total Calculated Bean Yield from Specified Rates of Application of Nitrogen and Phoephorio Acid, nnd.Potach, Predicted from the Cobb-Douglas Equation, for.Petino Been Data. 1957/58: e e e e e e e d e e e e Total Predicted and ObeerVeJ'Yielde for BERN P&tln° Field Data, 1957/58. D e e e e e Calculated finrginal Productivitieo of a Pound of Nitrogen in the Production ot_ Beans at Various Katee of Application of - Nitrogen and fieleoted Bean Prices, for Petino Fifild Data, 1957/58 e e e e e e e e e Calculated Harginal Productivities of n Pound of Phosphoric Acid in the Production of Boone at Various Rates of Application of Phosphoric Acid and Selected Bean Fricee. for'Pntino Field Data, 1957/58 e e e e e e e 60 61 64 66 71 72 73 74 FIGURE :0 a: I. b. 0. '0. vii Lie? 0? FIGURE* Total Yield with fiitrogen . Variable end.POU Fixea at Three Levels, PotincuLower Field Yield Data for Corn, 1957. a o I Q a o o I a o 46 Total Yield with 221106 Variable end flitrogen Fixed at Three Levels, for Petino Lower Field Yield Date for Corn, 195?- o 0 o o I a o 46 Scale Line for Nitrogen and P905 Increased in : fixed 1:1 PrOpcrticn for’Patino Lower Field Corn Yield beta, 1957 n o u a o I o n o o o u n o a 48 Total Ileld with Nitrogen Variable and.P¢0 Fixed at Three Levels, PutinOWUpper Field corn Eleld Data, 1957 o v o o c o o o o o a u 58 Total Xiald'with.P005 Iariable and Hitrogen Fixed at lures Levels, ficr Patino Upper Field Corn Yiela Data, 195?’OOIII‘IQQO§OIO‘OO. 5’8 ficalo Line for Nitrogen and P005 Increased in a Fixed 1:1 PrepSrtion, for Patina Upper.Pield Corn Yield Data. 1957 Q I I I O O I O C. I U C I O O 58 03 m3" T173331 1 T2133: Ifi’i‘zifiinfdlixfliilfi.zsliIP'.236 up Adfiuflmfit} Maj.) :.:1Cu:-::;;:-::IG L1=454C2F£3 13:5 9351;111:313 ii;3‘.3?7;"«3i{:}£ :81; Mg Qfiglnfargrfitggn fine-flew; 1);: ’r‘f'gmgrmjw Una. aspect of rartllizer resaarcn deals with.tha presence or absence or respanao 1n crap yields to fertilizer aypllcatlans. Howavar, once reapunaes have bean round to 9113:, the farmer needs to ounslficr fartillzsr alang with other reaouroon and practices in his farm managemant decisions. These decisions can be made moat efficiently 1f fertilizer information 13 prcviflad 1n the tern.or 1ncra~ mental rngponsa data. Ineromental response data show tha'auocsaalva ada1t10na ta yield rasulting tram suecnsaive fartillzar appliontldpn.. Regardingly, onaa research has shown that crap yields no reapond to tartlllzer, the max: stays in rasekroh.mre to estimata: (a) the lnaranental yielda fortncauing from airfarent rates or tartllizer appliaations unfier apaolried crap an& 2011 conditions, and (b) tha eoanamla Optimum quantity of fertilizer, conngerlng crap and fertilizer'prioaa and production costs. Farmara can be divlaed luto two groups! thaao who have ample capital and those who have limited capital. they are seldom interested in maximizing yields per acre, and not even the farmer with unlimited eapitai ie interested in unnimunwper acre yields: he is interested in hhgher acre yields only to the extent thigreeter production adds more to reuurne than to caste. the extent to which.higher yields increase profits depend on: _ (a) the rate at which inputs are transformed into crepe, and (b) the price ratio. Maximum profits come when the crop/fertilizer trans- formation ratio is equal to the fertilizer/crap price ratio: the transformation ratio declines with heavier fertilization rates under diminishing returns. The elape or the response function represents the incremental er'marginal yield due to small increases in fertilizer use. The farmer with.iinited capital needs this information in determining how mach fertilizer to apply. For inetenoel. suppose that a farmer with.limited capital can earn 82-60 return on tunde spent eieewhero in his business (each as motor fuel, crap need, or beg supplement). _. . .A..- A W ‘ v . ,_v , V .7 ‘— 7 _' 11161117, B. 0., "Methodological Problems in Fertilizer Use“, (in) 321211, E. In. Heady, 17:. 0., Blackmore, J., ‘Hethodolo§geal Prgge-rmren in the Economic Amalgam 0:; t 11 er Us Dar 3, Men, Iowa Estate College—“Frees, 6, 9113}; or , pp. 3. lie in given information showing that; one discrete level of fertilization, 30 pounds of nitrogen, will more-nee oat yield by 17 bushels. Eith oatsat 70 cents per bushel and nitrogen application coating 18 cents per pound, the tote]. return in $11.90 and the total cost in £35.40, a net of 2.16.50. However, the return per dollar spent on fertilizer (11.90336MO) in only $2.20 and the farmer will allocate hie scarce rundn where he can get £32.60. suppose, however, that the farmer ie given even three points from a response function moving: in. first 10 pounds of nitrogen has a marginal yield or 10 bushels; the second 10 pounds hoe n marginal yield of 6 bushels, and the third 10 pounds has a marginal yield of 2 bushels. with a unit caning $1.80, the first 10 pounds returns $5.89 per dollar invented in fertilizer, and the second return: $1.95. Hence, since the tamer can realize only 32.50 elsewhere in his business, he new is encouraged to invest in at least lo pound: of nitrogen. Clarion-1y, than, knowledge or the response function, coupled with information on the economics of fertilizer woman encourage a greater investment in this resource on the great majority of fame with limited capital. 4 The netted If research and form of presentation, when the findings and recommendations are in tome of "one discrete level. can lead the tamer to uee no fertilizer when fertilization actually represente a profitable investment within hie situation of limited capital. Knowledge of the responee function is equally important for the farmer with unlimited eopital. It ie known that the optimum or most profitable level of fertilization for these farmer-e ie defined in equation (1) 21:21 a? par where the term to the left of the equality ie the marginal yield or response and the term to the right ie the price ratio (price per unit of fertilizer divided by the price per unit of yield). The marginal yield ie the derivative of yield with respect to nutrient; it ie the 310]” of the response function for any particular input level. Thi- ie the type of information haeio for making recommendations to fax-mere who no): to maximize profite when unlimited capital in available to than. iwmniorozlronomie Intezrotion in Fer-til; 3:13P Hesterqgw Ae Johnson1 pointe out , ”fertilization research should be ‘— -— M A A 4+... 4‘ 1Johan-on. 6.1... "Interdisciplinary Considerations in Designing merimente to {study the Profitability of Fertilizer 030'. in Baton, Eel-we. 8.88.”, 3.0., Blackmore, Je, gge gi‘e.pe 22o r looked at from the point of vim: or an agriculturist rather than I'm tha confined viewpoints of ths farm management specialist, the soil Specialist, the marketing 01:00:41.1“. the mathematical statistician, or the specialln 1n leguminous nitrogen fixation”. Agronomna and omnomlata recognize that fertilizer recommendations should be! based on data and principle: dram In: both salmon. first, it 1. necessary that 33902103110 findings be avntlablo for.applioazion of tho relevant oaonomio principles. ntatlng that. find how much tortilla“- would I” unad- ‘I'ho 01001103110 13148131910 15. or course, quit. uterus without tho raaponao data to go with it. Rayner. agronomic data alono do not yrs-wide the bill! for efficient fertilizer use. 803:. of the reasons for the lack of integration of economic and agronomic principlea 1n tartlluer raseamh in tho past and at tho present time in many cases and. muntriea, as Haadyl points cu: are the: following: (a) lack at training of agricultural ecnnomata 1n matkwmatlcal economics and statistical techniques to davalop the kind of estimates for economic analyais. ____ ‘4. . “A w .— vv— w w v ———-—v 18mm, 3.32... Heady, 3.0. “Over-all Economio Gonna-ru- tions in Fertilizer Use", (in Baum. Ed... Heady, E.0., Peach, J.‘I‘., Hildra‘bh, 3.0., “figg‘tiliaer Innovationg ang gigsqurogflsg', Am”, Iowa Stat? Collega Proms, 7195?, 1313.128. 6 (b) overspeaialization in landvgrant collagen and othsr rodenroh institutions has not always encouraged sufficient unaporativo work. (0) improved statistical techniques far handling multifi variable tortillas: eXperimants have been emphasized only racontly. (d) in many areas of tbs United atatea, fertilizer became an important factor of production only recently. (0) the raluotanca or agronomiats to consider economic Optima studio. as a part or their resaaroh program duo, in part, to a lack of understanding of the mathamatioal procedural; used by the economists. (f) agronomiatll typo studies to establish.rosponso and relate it to soil characteristion rathmr than to dotcrmino the marginal had been interested largely in Variance- quantitioa And the aptimum use of fartilizor. # __._‘. AA “A; .4 ____. A“ A; .4-‘4 _‘ —J- lfiaady, E.O. Peaek, J.T., “A Fertilizor*Production surfaoo with specifications of Economic Optima for Corn Grown on Calaaraoua 153 311% Loam”, ggurnal of Fang Economggo, Volume 36, August 1954, pp; 466. "fl" momma 2 Ti ItUJdbfiod FJHG” 3% Ana EHEL 0.NCETI O, i i lulu}: EA: 102‘ Thgbggoduction Function in Pa; :3; 11m 2~3"'~fi;~ As has been pointed out by Johnsonl, tho typical ex;oriment deoign inroatigatos a production function or the form of equation (2) (2) i 3 ft”,:, K / L4......2{n) § u where Y 18 yield in buahels per aoro; N, ? ani E are the uaoally investigated independent variable: or levolo of fertilization; xé......xn include Variables "fixed” at a cortain level (oultivations, insect control, rotations, Ph Invola. varieties, drainago, soil uniformity, oto.). U is the variation in yield not explainod by the experimental variations in the indepandont variables. T3 n or Kari 'atio .~ Produotion functions express the funokional relationship between ronouroa inputs and product output . Th. contentional procedure in a production function __ “4‘ .L A __ v—w ~— lJohnaon, G.L.,!Planning Agronomic-Economic Research in View of Roodlta to Iato' (in) Sana, E.L., l=¢dr, 3.0., Pesok, J.?., Hildroth 0.6., “bertiliLer =Innovations and Rooouro , Tie 10% a State ouiiabo EToaa, Ar.es, glowa, I§57, fihapfor 19,p pp. 219. .A... ‘——,—~=' ‘— —r v v w—v study is to predict the total output curve or surface as an estimating (or regression) equation. Maximization concepts help locate cuch.economic optimum as the quantity or‘r to produce maximum profit and the least cost combination of fertilizer F1 and F2 to use in producing that amount ofjproduct output Y, and also how these Optima shift with price change..1 In a function such as equation (:5), in‘whidh 3c 3 yield of crap P0 3 price of crap ’1 3 fertilizer input F2 3 fertilizer inpnt P11 3' pricc ct fertiliser’input 31 ‘Pm 3- price of fertilizer input 1'2 Xd...?..x, ‘ input. fixed at upcoificd conditions. " 3 profit when 921; constant (4 an... ) m-c A W .7. ._ —.- fir.— v 7w ’7 130mg”, 3. L. , “Interdisciplinary consideration: in ‘ Designing Emerinentl to Study the Profitability of Fertiliser Use“, (in) Baum, E. I... Heady, E. 0., Bllchflfl‘ JO. fl. a;t., Chaptflr 2' p. 27. defines the most profitable amount of F1 to use with the constant. amount 0! P2. Under ordinary campetitlva con- ditione, the condition for maximizing profits is defined as in equation (5) (5) Mr : ch . rye-13:1 n O 3'5"). I: the most profitable combination of F1 and F2 in producing: a given amount or 20 is desired, equation (6) defines the least cost combination of F1 and F2 to use in producingx the amount of Yc under consideration: (5) 2.1.3 1”}. (123 d? 2 :9 ‘6‘5? rt . A: the condition defined in equation (5) ie, for F1 -and :3 respectively, the slap. or the;production function defined in equation (5). these oonditionc permit deter- mination of tho moat profitable (least-coat) combination of F1 and F2 to use in obtaining a given yield (where‘ic in hold constant). When it is desired to determine the most profitable amount: of F1 and F to use and at Ya to produce, the 2 derivatives for profit with respect to F1 and F2 are set equal to zero, and solved simultaneously for F1 and FP‘ Having eecurcd r and F in this way, the values are l 2 substituted in equation (3) and solved for‘Yc. io omega :5 STAT I 3T1 CM, M 3‘13. Siflfiifi i-‘J‘ETfi Int rgduct 19g . - when the values assumed by one variable (If) dependcn (i.c., are a function of) the values taken by one or more other‘variablee (X1,X3.....Xn) a functional relationship is defined- ! is called the I'dcpendent variable' and the variables on which‘! depends are referred to no “independent variables". correlation analysis given e measure of how the dependent variable changes with e given change in the variable or variablee on which it depende. This measure in an 'eetimating equation' which malice possible estimates of the dependent variable from the independent variable or variables. Correlation.cnelyeie cleo providee a measure of the eccurecy of Inch estimates - “the standard error of estimate“: and finally, 'the coefficient of correlation“ tells the degree of correlation. When the enelyeie is limited to two variables the method ie celled lsimple correlation“ but it is often necessary to include the influence of several independent veriablee to explain the variation in the dependent variable and this is known on "multiple correlation“. 11 Gganhlc Annlyein of Functional Relationsh Ja.~ A method of plotting the ante and a method peculiarly suited to the ennlyeie of functional relationships is that or the scatter diagram. Here one variable ie scaled on the x axis, the eecond on the‘! axis, and the paired values or the two variables are plotted on these eoaiee. Because of the characteristic of the data, the tendency of the point: ie to eeetter diagonally across the diagram from the lower left hand to the upper right. When two variiblee are plotted in the scatter diagram, one ordinarily should be characterized ne indepennent (in the present study it ie fertilizer input) and the other an dependent variable (being output or crop yield). the independent variable is the one upon which.the variation in the second scene to depend. The independent variable is ordinarily'plotted on the}{exie and the flependent variable on the‘! axia- Th. . inn Benn o .* gathematioally computed line! may be penned.through.the date, which.ere celled I'2Linee of average relationship“, or 'regreeeion lines", because they reveal the typical change in the dependent variable'! which has accompanlad a given changa 1n the independent variable or variablaa. This average relationship may he datermined math- ematically by tha mathod of least squares. In computing tha equation for an estimating equation, an.‘a‘ value must be accurad'whioh'will be the value of the regression lino at its origin, and a “b" value, which will desorlbfi tha average changg ln‘Y with,a 31Ven change in x. When thus: two values are obtainad, a complete description or & regression line 13 secured, the mathematical characteristle'cf which.may‘bo described in equatlan (7) for functional relationships with.ona indapandent variable. (’7) _{ Eu 3 a § bx To obtain the ”a“ value, the follawlng equation 19 used: (8) av? 1x32: -;_x gig :3 1x5 - (xx)? The farmula for “b“. nhowing ~ha average change in'Y for n givnn change in x 1: given 1n (9) (9) b: a ZXYg-HZX g}; a 1x3 - (81:02 If two or'mora independent variables are used.to naplain tho change: in a depandent variable. 1: becomes possible to measuro the influence or each or these (X2 and X5, for example) when the Influenos of the ether (x2 and X5) 13 considered. 13 ThQ:Standard_Errorflpf Estimgt§.~ Error must be expected in all estimates made tram regression equations. If there are variables which have been ignored in computing the regression equation and.they are important, the estimates mafia may be very poor and the actual observations may scatter widely about the regroaslon lino. Since the daparturo of the observations from the line of regression is due to such "other” factors a3 have been suggested, these deviations are knnun as ”rcaifluals". Thay are rsaidualu 1n the sauna, than, that after X has been used to QXplain the variation of Y there may remain a residual variation whioh.1s due to a large number of forces which has been ignorua in the correlation. If, on the other hand, the raaiauals in simple oorrolstion are not due to a mass or other influences, but can be explained by the introduction of one or morn sadltlonal inaspsndant variables. the analysis should bs converted to a problem in multiple correlation. The new function with several indepafidont variables may providc s‘bsttar explanation of the variation in Y, and one svidenoo of this will be a reductisn 1n the residuals. Thu next step in the analysis will be to measure the 14 residual variation. If it proves to be small, the forces ignored in the function as stated have little influence on I. In oraer to gain some idea or the ndqquacy of the rogroaalon equation as an eXpIanntion of tho vr‘iationo In I, it 13 accessory to have a mathematical devioo'whloh V111 measure the scatter of the points around the regression lino. If the regression line 13 a good fit and the aotual data plot dloso to it, thorn 19 indioation that the values of I are related to those of x in the manner described by the regression equation. In thin noon, the derived.mathenat1oal measure or the residual variatlon ohould give a low value. Should the points scatter widoly from the regression line. tho us. of that estimating equation as an explanation of the variations in I must be questioned and any estimate or‘! baaod.on its functional relationship to X must be expootod to be Inaccurate. In this tune. the mathematical measure of thezrooldnnlo would have I rulativoly large value. The neanuro of the scatter of the pout: 13 known on the 'atandordforror of ootimate'. It In 13 used.to symbolize tho computed Values of I, nnd.¥ to symbollzo the actual value. of I. this pronoun of calculating tho standard crror 15 of estimate is as follows in equation (10), where By Mixes the standard error of estimate: 10 ‘ ’ ay=\l 11W"??? H The interpretation of the ctnnainrd error of estimate is eimilnr to that of the standard deviation. It: may be said that approximatelr'fiafi of the points in the scatter diagram will be within the range or the regression line plus and minus one standard error. nonsurongng cg Correlg}: on.- f The estimating equation-reveals the change in the dependent Variable which typically accompanies a given elmngo in x. The scatter of points around a regression line gives a fir-t visual impression of the extent to which the independent variable, or nrinblcc, actually cucceed in explaining the Variation in the dependent variable, and whether useful estimates of it can be made from those relations. The standard error of estimate gives a measure of this scatter. How, it in desired to obtain one summary figure which will indicate the 'extent' to which two or more variable: are correlated. This should be A pure number, so that the units in which the values are quoted will. not affect it. It should have known linitc no that it may be readily 16 interpreted. The “coefficient of correlation“ (symbolized by 'r’ for simple correlation and by "a" for multiple correlation) is such a measure. Eiatiom}mvlained v The Coefwnt of Detenninfitiogow '1lm procedure in oorrelation analysis ie to nonpute the'per can! of the variation of Y‘whieh is exnlained by the independent variablei. iroditionelly, thin result is obtained by first competing the per cent variation of I'whdoh.ie not explained'oy the independent variable or Striablee. (a) The garietion of rhino Value of 6:12: oinoe the variation of I can be defined no the etendcrd deviation squared, the calculation in mode substituting the Yaluee tor Y, 1‘3 and H in the formula (11): (11) o 2 -? _o 9: Just no the variation of Y is the etandard deviation squared, the variation of I not explained by x,ie the etanderd error or eetimate squared (Byg). It the variation of I were completely explained by X, all observations of I would tell on the regression line and the value or By and Eye would be zero. 17 The larger the value of 6:; end oyg the lean perfect the exylanation of the variation o! I‘by the independent variable or variables. and the more important in determining Y are other factors, which were not included in the function. Elvira‘fore, the larger {Bye the gnome:- the per cent of ”the variation of 2 not- oxylnined by 2!. (12) eye 8 2x3.- Egg) 4 Vb tug]. n (c) We?ACr-zlnfi"ain‘thew’e’qriotion‘pf Y}? Jalainguuvv The variation not explained by X is divided by the variation of I, that in, Byz/yg and by subtraction then from one resulte the per cent of the variation of X emlained by the inde- pendent variable or variables, which is one or the neat useful resulte in correlation analysis, and is known ee the 'ooetrioient of determination“, as crown in (1:5) (13) coefficient of denomination 3: 1 «- 3:72 "'8" 6‘1" The per cent, Byalfl‘ya ie :cnmm no the “coefficient of non detemination‘ because it represente the per cent of the variation of if not explained. by the inciepondont variable. W 00. ff 1m 01‘ Germaine-c i-fhon the etamiard error of 18 estimate is zero there is perfect correlation. It tho standard error of estimate is zero, actual ano estimated values of‘! are identical. That is, tho regression equation prOViaoa a perfect fit to the actual values or I} and the variation 01'! is completely exploinod by tho indeyandsnt variable and complet aly fieynmflent u; on: it. In that oaoe one value or Sy' 0 and the ratio aye/Cr? will be zero imlioating zero per cent of the variation explained by‘tho indop ndont Variable or variables. I! the standard error is equal to, or nearly equal to tho standard oeviation, there io no oorrolation. Unoor this condition the value or the ratio on/C‘yg would be one, or approximately one, tho yer cont of the variation unexplainod.wou1d be near 100 per cont and.tho variation explained would be near zero. In this case, the cooffioiont or actormination will approximate zero. Tho 'oooffioiont of correlation” is bogod on the coefficient of determination, that 19, the par cont of La variation explained by tho inaopondant variable. Thus, when tho standard error or estimate-is zero an& the explained variation is thoroforo 100 per cent, tho ooefficiont of oorrolation has a value of one. If tn. Variation Lunoiplainofi (SW3) 33100113. be £3 largo 19 shoulLi be as large as too total variation 5'3“? than the unexplained variation is 100 per cent, the oxylained variation is zero, and the coefficient of correlation is also zero. The ooofrioient of correlation is a pure number not influenced.by the unito in Ufilafl tho data are quoted and it is computed as in oiuation (1%) (14) ~ W 6'!“ when.more than one independent Variable is used to oXplain the variation of the dependent variable, ”R“ in need to eymbolizo the ooefrioiont of multiple correlation, being conceptually the some as the oootfioiont of correlation. 1‘2th of: @331: tion 3.0311211: gu- A H5 Simply beoauoo a high value or P. is obtained in a correlation armiysio. it cannot be assumed that a valid, reliable, oni suitable funotion h&8 been oetobiiexoo. There are acme further tests that sheila be node to establish the reliability of the roanlto from correlation analysis. (a) Validity Tog§.v The volifiity toot consists of a critical appraisal of rooulto to assure tho reoeorohor‘that the relations aaoumed in the function are corrootg‘that the rolntionohipo do not violate :oanona of reasonableness: that tho ohoervod results are consistent among thomselvos and that the terms included actually reflect the Variables they aro intondofl to rnyrooonto The voliaity toot rests partly on theory, partly on ozporimontution w to otuor alternati?o (auctions, and partly on the comparison 01‘ the attained result. with those aohiond in other similar studies. his toot in important booauoo whom the relations revealed or. not valid, in tho oonoo tho torn is used horo. tho: likely will not be stool. ovor a poriod or timo'fiithor, no vary poor estimates may result. Fhroharmoro, wrong unavora may be suggested for analytical and Operational problems and easy satisfaction with.high 8': values may discourage further roooaroh.whionuvould product muoh.b¢$t¢r re B‘dlt 3. (b) _Boiiabiiiix;§gg§v- Another reason to take a aocond critical look at correlation rooulta is that they may look roliabiiity. Tho most obvious case is when random aam;laa are used. If nany ouch.aamp1es were taken from the some pepulation, can can be sure that the regression coefficient. for example, woulfl differ from sample to sample: that a sampling distribution could be constructed and tho standarfl error of the regression coefficients estimated. or course, 5y (tho standard error of actinato) and 6‘? must also b9 expected to differ somewhat, from sample to sample, so thot “R“ which.éepondc on than, will also have a nonpling distribution and ito own standard error. Tonto or significance or the rngraacion coefficient can be made under a null hypothesis. The hypothesis in that tho pepuiation voice of the regression coefficients are zoro and that the cczimatod value is one to sampling error or other chance «lemontc in the cchrimcnt. is Tintnerl points out, the logic of tho teats or cigaitioanoo consists in determining what is the probability that certain deviations from a postuintod iypothocia (called the null hypothosic) could have orioon by chanoc. If this pmifrability 1:: email, then, the chinoao are that the null hypothesis does not hold. What is necdod to test this hypothcoio is a critical ratio subject to probability distribution. For thio test, A“ A Aw _._ iii _ A. A A m ‘ ‘ .T —V —v "'- 1Tintnor, G.,'Significanccriccta in Production Function Roooarohfi, (in) Hoody, Er0., Johnson, G.L., Hardin, L.8., £0 21 0. Chapter 14. pp. 1380 g: i the standard errcr of the sampling distribution or the regroaaion coeffieiants is as follows: (115) we regression ooaffioien : _A * .L (T'3 ~x~P x (1 d) The Gritiaal ratio is tha diffwrenee bfituusn the hypothetical regressiua ifisfilcient zero and the unnerved vain. of regraaaion coefficient over the standard error of tha rsgronaion coefficient as ahawn below in (15) (is) t t .ggyreggiqn cqetficient 7 # Standard arrar of regreasion cceffioiani {‘3 08 C EN’T HR 4 ILYJ’JJ. ffflTAi. HUME M43) :30 ”123-105 (:2? DATA who experimental work to actornina fertilizer input- crop output relationships was conducted coOperotively by tho Colombia Project of Michigan state University, the Facultcd dc.A3rcnomia.ot the Universidod fiaoional dc Colombia at Palmira (Colombia) and a Colombian former, Honor Edgardo Patino. Doctor Leonard Kyle and Hr. Gerald Trant from the Agricultural Economic Department; 3r. Kirk Lawton from the Soil Department, at Michigan ototc University, and members of the staff from the Michigan Agricultural Experiment Station, participated in the design of tho cchrincnt and colloction cf the experimental data. Th D‘-.t' .- Thc corn experiments were developed at SencrtPatino‘c farm near Florida (Colombia) on a well drained clay loam coil. The Ochrimcntc incluaod all three of tho primary plant nutricnts, nitrogen, phosphoric acid and potash, the first two in varying combinations and the last generally constant. The corn experiments were conducted in two fields which 24 will be called Patino Loner Field and Potino Upper Field respectively. Both experiments had the some design and in both the some trentmcnt levels of fertilizer were used. Eight treatment lcvclc were included for nitrogen, ccvcn treatment levels for phcaphoric acid, with,potach gonorcliy conctnnt. Those trcatmcnt levels measured in pounds per core are: H — O 2 40 60 80 100 180 140 P - O :3 4.0 60 BO 100 120 Except for the zero treatment lcvclc, potash was hold constant at 60 pounds per acre. The levels of fertilization for corn arc shown in detail in Table i, and the design of the experiment in Table 2. Thc_8ccn_Datn.- The objective of this exocrimcnt conducted also in Potino'c farm rrcn.00tch P loo? to January 1958, was to evaluate the rccponcc of beans to different combinations of fertilizer inputs. Five treatment levels were included for nitrogen, five treatment levels forjphoopnoric ncid, with.potosh generally constant. Tomcc treatment levels measured in poundc per core arc: n - O 2 40 60 80 P ~ 0 £6 50 75 100 Except for the zero trontmont levels, potash was held constant at 40 pounds per core. TABLE 1 szst c? FamTILIaATIOH Pea THE away :xrgmlxxnws, PATINO 1.0mm AND “mm mama mum, 1957. .__ .4‘ 4— A. __. A L ~__._.‘_- v' .— fil wfi— v. w“ ‘v v—V v W i" Plant Rutrienta Plant fiutrianta (Pounds per Acre) (Pounds per Acre) N P206 K20 H P205 1.20 O O O 60 60 60 O 0 ' 60 60 100 60 O 20 60 60 1:20 60 0 4O 60 o 60 60 80 o 60 O 80 60 80 2:0 60 o 100 so so 40 so 0 1,, 60 80 80 60 80 120 60 20 O 60 - 20 20 60 100 0 60 20 4O 60 100 2’0 60 20 60 60 100 60 60 2.0 80 60 100 100 60 2.0 100 60 100 3... 60 20 120 60 120 O 60 40 0 60 120 40 60 40 20 60, 1:30 80 60 40 4O 60 1% 15-30 60 40 60 60 40 BO 60 140 O 60 40 120 60 140 20 60 140 40 60 60 O 60 140 60 60 60 20 60 ‘ 140 80 60 60 4O 60 140 100 60 140 120 so T 2"; Plug 22 Ewmuzm-z’z‘m. DESIGN 02" mix; can zm"1;;‘21x:2-3 .16 .17 .17 .10 .19 0 .05 .16 .17 .17 .18 .19 10 .03 .16 .17 .17 .10 .10 25 .01 .05 .06 .00 .06 .06 60 .006 .03 .00 .03 .03 .05 70 .005 .00 .02 .03 .02 .02 100 .002 .01 .01 .01 .01 .01 v—n— q..- w. ‘v—w v .— V , ‘ 8001101: per acre. 75 mwma 6 WALUATION, cummmzmgs mm In: 1.10;": 10:43 ‘ggaluatigg.* Eagegimentgl_flotg and Gonnaggigl_Far§§.- Comparing thfi conditions faced by the researcher varking with experimental plots and the situation faced by the Operator’on a commercial farm, it can be seen that, even though, the number of independent variables usually included in experimental work in very small nnd.many problems encountered.by the farmers (rotations, ate.) cannot b0 solved entirely within the framework or a ninglo cxperiment, the information obtained from it can be combined and improved by subaoquent research leading to better and broader knowledge of tha functional relationship: involvad. Th0 elements oonnidired “fixed“ in oxperimantai work ouch.aa the recommended.practiooa, are also controllable by the farmer. The trouhlesome element seems to lie on the difference of levels at which.non¢oontroliablo, non-studied variables are fixed in the experimantal work and on the farm. Each individual experiment field has certain unique characteristics associated with it, which are the detarminant factors when the results from the experimental field arc trying to be generalized for a large number of forms. Thus, the problem, is to try to reduce the variance in the experimental results to conform closer to those on the farm, enabling tho economic optimum conditions to be defined more accurately. This problem, on the other hand, is nggrnvatcd'by the desire of the researcher of minimizing within field variability choosing the location of the experiment in auoh,n way, that generally the 167913 at which those uncontrolled variables are fixed in the experimental work and tho levels at which they are tixod on tho commercial farms nro pushcd still fartnor apart. Vagigngg.- The unotudied and uncontrolled variables causing largo amounts of uncxplnined betwecnuplot variance may be important elements when determining: (a) tho apprOprinto mathanntionl function to fit, and (b) the Optima located onasalcctod function. One cause or this unoxolained variance is believed to be the small also of tho plots usually used in experimental work. However, as has been suggcotcd, he variance present in yield data obtained from small experimental plots migr bc highor than the amount of variance experienced by tho ?7 Operator cn-a commercial form in which larger areas are involvcfi. This is u very important point to oonsiior, because the accuracy of tho recommendations undo to farmers nopenda to a great extent on how representative of tnc conditions on the averngc turn are the estimates secured from experi- mental work. A: to ways to handle this problem, the following have been suggested: (a) Incrcnoc in the Sizcugt_tho Engarimontnl Platon— Larger plots should be used in experimental work. Khan the causes of the variance are randomly aistributod throwghout the experimental area. the use of larger plots will be indicated, but, to tho extent that the causes of variance are not randomly distributed but arc correlated.bctwccn chnccnt small plots, replications of plots become relatively more effective than larger plots in reducing variance. (1:) Poisoning Young; The cnuacs of unexplained variance might be invcstigatod and measured and incluaed in the study no independent variables. However, obstacles are encountered at present to 78 study accurately this point because appr0pr1ate methods of measurement are still not very well developed. Va11d1tz of Eagerlmgntal Results over Time.- Yisld data from one your eXperimental work has been analyzed in previous chapters only. As has been pointed out previously, the uncontrolled and unstudled varlables present in the eXperinental work influence the results in such.s way that, based on one year's date, generalizations cannot and must not be made trying to extend the analysis to future years. The U element analyzed above In likely to change year after year and predictions based on such.unstsble ground V111 have a large percentage of probsbxlitiee to be wrong. Preblems of residual fertility accumulation and depletion and rotation effects become important when lens run conclusions are to be drsvn teen the experimental data and long run decisions are to be made on commercial terms. Conelus10g3.* Three sets of yield data were analyzed in the present study. 79 The first one. yield data for corn Patina Lower Field 195? included nitrogen and phosphoric acid as the independent variables; with potash.gonera11y held constant at 60 pounds per core. Two production functions or the type of equations (17) and (18) above were fitted to the data. Statistical measurements indicated that'tns cross product type or production function fitted the dots better than the square root production function. As it was seen before, the economic Optima conditions are based both.in the physical functional relationships and in the price conditions for fertilizer inputs and product Output existing at that time. If the price relationships involvod change, a new optimum amount of fertilizer inputs and nutrient combine. ticns to apply become profitable as determined,hy the new nutrient/crop price ratio existing site: the change. This point is generally overlooked in the present fertilizer'recommendations‘whieh.are being given to farmers. ‘ It is thejprinoipnl reason why a new approach inte~ grating agronomic and economic concepts is being used in the design of fertilizer-experiments Which allows the location of points at which.mnxinum profits from a given 80 yplioation of fertilizer nutrients are possible. At the some time, recomncnlaticns to farmers are made in terms or maximum.profita in which changing price conditions of fertilizer and/or craps are considered, that is, these recommendations are mode more realistic approaching situations which.orc ucuolly {need by the farmers in the planning of their fertilizer prcgrams. A significant response to both nitrogen and thSphOP10 acid was found to exist for this set or data. The economic Optima point «no computod. with respect to nitrogen it was found to be located outside the range of experimental observations. Therefore, the figure or 530.24 pounds per acre of nitrogen 13 an extrapolation and cannot'bo uaod for actual fertilizer racemnondation purposes. However, it does indicate tnat further research using higher fertilizer treatment levels would be very useful to complement the experimental resultcgresented hero. The Optimum amount of phosphorous to uce was found to be 40.98 pounds per core which is within the experimental range observed. The same two functions above indicated were fitted to the second set of data for corn Patina Uppcr Field 195?. This yield data included nitrogen nnd.phospnoric acid as 81 the two independent variables, with.potash generally constant at 60 pounds per acre. The two functionc iniicatei gave a very poor fit of the yield data, with the crooa product proiuotion ruzction considered.to be a slighzly bottor representation of the functional relationships involved. The most profitable amount of fertilizer input to use was JOHpUted using the cross proiuot equation and was found to be a ncgativa quantity 01-62.?0 pounds of nitrogen per acre and 41.46 pounds of pncaplsorio acid per core. The predicted yield computed for the profit maxiniza- tion point was 30.85 bushels per acre. A significant response was recorded only for phocphorio aoifi with no reoponsc on yield recorded for nitrogen. The third set of antn for bean Patina 1957/58 was fitted with the same two production functions previously cited and'with a Cobb~Douglas function of the type of equation (13) obovo. Based on tho statistical nonouroncnts derived, the Cobb-Douglas function nonconsidorofl n more opprOpriatc fit for this act of yield iota. Economic optima quantities of fertilizer inputs to apply were computed using this equation ani‘tho results ehcwad that 56.9 pounds of nitrogen per acre ought to be ussd for profits to be at a maximum, indicafiing a sigh ~ nitloant response to this element. A slight response to phosphoric acid was recorfied inflicatad by an Optimum amount of 15.0 pounds per acre to be used. The ostluated yield as gutai using this functional relationship was reuni to ba 14.3 muahels per acra. The same onnacpta on haw the npfilmum amount at nutrients to use are dependent on tha fertilizer/crap price relation- ship existing at tho time an thny were explained above for the corn efipcrlmsnts are velld in this case and they must be taken into onnziierwtion. In"). 11 (33132033.- alts fer tha 3gggggg§gg.~ It has been rcmarkedl “that the only time an experiment can be preperly designed in after it has been completed“. Ono sometimes finds, after a act of experimente have v -—v— — ‘7 w v— 1fiox, 6.52.?” Hunter, J.S., "Tb-w mlo‘mtion and Rzplcitatlon of Heaponaa aurraoes‘, (as cited in) Mason, David 3., “Statistical Frnbloms of Joint Research“, Jaurnnl of Farm Eceqogiog, Vuluna 69, May 19d7, p. 371. 83 been made, that one or more important variables have been overlooked or that more could have been learned it the factor-e could have been varied. over different rangee. Al has been the. can in the present study, additional information would have been extremely useful it higher levels of fertilization would have been included for Corn Patina Lower Field 1967', in which the economic optimum point eetmate'wae well beyond the levels within which experimental observaucne were recorded. Thus, the results from the above analysis have indicated the direction in which further research work with fertilizer may be pretitably carried out in corn and bean orapl. “the” reculte "cm to smut the need for additional experimental work in the Ounce. Valley, Colombia, for corn and been: and other important crepe which over the yam would provide useful and dependable information for making fertilizer recommendations to farmers. As he. been shown in this study, agronomic and economic concepts are closely interrelated in fertilizer research. However. economic maceration. are still neglected in the current fertilizer recommendations that are given to I fame". In Colombia, as elsewhere. this in also true and 84 it ie nocoeenry thnt reocarotore planning future fertilizer reeearch.work be able and willing to recognize these inter- relationships and to include them in their ctudionl It in not on coey task to obtain cooperation, and in many oneee to be willing to cGOperato in research work which seems outside one's area of specialization or interests. This is particularly true in an environment in which efforts toward this and have not been nude yet. Nevertheless, this OOOperction in neceeenry and prdbnbly bndly needed in countries like Colombia. in which agricultural developv ment prejectc are undcr'woy and where capital and trained technicians are usually in short supply. A fertilixer reeearohqproject deeigned.to provide experimental data when plant nutrient inputs are varied over different ranges end from which economic Optima eati- nates can be located, certainly represents a considerable improvement over experimental designo from which.merginnl productivitiee and economic optimum cannot be determined. no a matter of foot, more information is provided by design: of the type considered herein both or agronomic and economic interact. The ratio or useful information to expenditures in probably higher for agronomic-economic 1:an for purely 85 agronomic designs. _§ignificnngc cg rccnl§o_jor tho Furfior.~ The analysis of experimental work presented in this ctufly is ratncr limited in scape with reopoct to coil conditions, crops, and growing cannons. For the reasons stated cloonnerc, seldom are any reconmenfintlons made Upon the basis of n alnglo experiment such no this onc. Additional work is nocfied to oupyort or dong the Optimum plant nutrient treatment octimntcc precentod hero and before rollahlo rocomcndationa can be none to farmers for rational planning or their'fcrtilizor*programs. Historically, this information has not been available to farmers for the vary simple reason that fertilizer research has been conducted indcnondcntly from any economic oonaiderationa. ‘Tha farmers arc being copplicd.nizh fartilizor infoan~ ntion in which, implicitly or oXplicitly, the conclusion in Doing drawn that the moat conquntc level of fertilization in the one at which.naximum yields For acre are attained. - As has been 32mm, maximum yields per com- and maximum profits from a given application of fertilizcr arc seldom 88 located at the same level. - Therefore, the dolombian farmer in the Canoe Valley and, it is suspected, elsewhere elongiend across the main agricultural regions or South America, ought to be supplied with fertilizer information in which recommendations are made to maximize profit instead of yields. when resources are so tar-out of adjustment as other similar studies in the Cauce'Valley show they are} hit. of internation provided by partial etudiee and preliminary surveys or the fertilizer problems or a given area, are perhaps the “at way and the most economic oneto promote a reallocation of those resources even though more refined and elaborated etudiee may prove to be useful afterwards. If reliable information could be secured with respect to the returne the Colombian farmer in the Cauce Valley is earning an inputs other than fertilizer in his bucineee, e coupariacn or their marginal productivitiee would provide an additional tool of decision-making to farmers for whcm limited capital in an important consideration. in surveys or the Colombian agriculture show a rate of increase in the agricultural production higher than that eccmnpliehed during the past year. will be needed to keep pace with the increasing pepulation and improving levels .__._. 1Trent, G. 1., 92. git. or living. Colombian farmers will certainly be required to increase the productivity of their farms. Fertilizer, as well as other forms of capital and ”know how" representing technical improvements in agri- culture een make an important contribution toward that Gflde 88 M‘PifiEDIX A (A) The Cob‘erouglac equation in of the form of equation (1) (1) YO : a o Ilbl 6 Phi; e K 133 in which Io is the predicted yield, the tom ”a“ is a. constant, and bl, b8, b3 are the regression coefficients and the elasticitiec of the dependent variable with respect to each dependent variable, that is, the percentage change in. the dependent variable associated with one per cent airings in the dependent vnria‘ole. the Cobb-Jouglas function becomes easier to manage in logarithmic form such no equation (2) (if) 103. Yo a: log. a 4 bl loam ; b3 logd’ <1 b3 log. K (B) The marginal phyeicel productivity in this function is defined in the equation (5) 1’ (5’%1¥::ble%rg in which :4 takes different value: according to the treat- ment levels specified. In the some way it is possible to compute the marginal productivitiee for P and X. from equation (3), equation (4) is derived indicating he condition of higher profit point: (4) b1 0 “Y‘s "' Pn C 0 H in which Pn is the price of (he) nitrogen. 89 The name condition can be derived for P nnd.K. The exeroalion (4) is need now to derive another equation, solving for»! (or P or X) such as (5) (5) N . b1 0 YB 13"” The expression.§§ is a constant K I. n 1 (KO for P, and K3 for K) and.now the equation for yield can be expressed an in (6): b1 (6) Y0 : 8. O (311 I Y0) i (K2 I Y°)b2 c (I: Q :{O)b3 3 and in logarithmic forms as in tsprnosion (7): (7) log;¥c : iog.n f b1 103.):1 { b1 log. Yo fb? leg. K2 f f b2 10g.Yo f b5 log. K3 i b3 log.'Yo or in a more abbreviate form cucn.ae (8): (8) 1051 Y0: log. a f b1 log.X1 ¥ b3 log'xp ‘ b3 log.K3 1~b1~b9~b3 (C) To work with the Cobb—Douglas equation, constants K In. and K,, are first computed, being necessary to know (5, u 1: the prices of N, P, and K, from equation (5). Then an estimate or yield: (Yo) can be made using equation (8) and converting the logarithm into a natural nuancr. How, the Optimum qunntitiea of N, P, and K, can be estimated from equatien (6) substituting the appropriate values in it. Finally, estimated. marginal physical. productivitiea can be computed substituting; the corresponding; values in equation ((3), and at the Efigh1‘3mf1t point $37.; emmllty (4) must be true. 91 BIBLIonRAPHI (a) gunk! and gook Arfiiolgs.~ Baum, K. L., "eady, E. P. "Over-all Economic Consideration- ln Fartillzer Uaa',1n 38“.; 3:- no, NOW, 55:. 0. X‘BEGK’ 1’. To. Hildflth, G. .0. 11 Reggggfgflgga, Th9 Iowa state U0 Lflgfi rress, Amen, Iowa, 96 , Chapter 19. Croxton, i. H., Gordan, D. J., 53F133§°§§3§51 gratisyggg. Plant 10. Hg11, Ina., 1965, Bacon 3 on. Hat-r, 60.11 3., 'Eoonomlc Incorprutatlan at Production Function: Estimatos“. (1n Kandy, E. 0., Johnson, G. Lu Hardin L. 8., R sou L S . Haady, E. 0., 'fiothndologionl Probluno in Fertlltxar Us.“ EGAJ. ib. OI . Elam“. J thCii 43-01 " 31.. t L . an r931. Amen, owa, § , Chap or He‘d: E. 0., ”Rulationshlp of Scale Analynistc Productivity ‘nslyazl", 3 G L “836? £10 0- 01313130“ 0 ho flax-din o E. our r0 i; L 'R . .- 8a~;’ L a‘ff m 81;t, ago 10!: ‘ baptor a. Heady, s. 0. "Technical Considnrat1ons 1n F.3t1mat1nc Production Funatlonn', £193”. .5- 0.. Johann: 3081‘. Hardin, Lo 3., Re a P 1 tn in Pa ova dta be can ?r9:1, aAues, own. .aptar 1. Johnson, 619nm L., “Interiinaiplinary Consldoratlons 1n Designing Experiments to Study tho Profitabllliy of Furtilizar Ugo“, 38m, E. 1". 30$”. E; 00' 315mm. J.’ P- ~ A ‘; f F Johnson, G. 1..., '2‘Mmm1ngi 33rcmmqlc-Economic Research in View of 9:3ulta to Date“, (in) Baum, 5. "2..., ”adv, 23.. 0., 1123022, J. ‘1‘.,Z":I1.l;1ret31, C. G... Pert11iven InnOV”t12n "ad “aanufioe ""3 The Iowa State b01¢b arrasa, Ad? 3, Iowa, 199? CM-.tvr 3.9- Maeon, David Du, "Functional R,Ju 13 131 r”“°“1“'rt 1 9aai~na for Ckaraoteriz in" fieapmnse Curves and Surfaces", (in) Banta, En 11. Lynn... 9;. do. 421% 1.119196, Jo, ””1” V‘ 10'21081 ”recedures in the i399 nonio 1n~‘v~13 of Fnr'TTi.u. Q :§ , Iowa “Sana -o-:eéo tress, 1563,:OYER,‘1953, Lprier 0 Mills, Frederick, 1n:ro.act10n tn 9: t1 1393,122nry 91h and COO, ”B’s! form”... 1:?56. Rubi-31233011, I... 8.. Johnson, G. L. Davis, J. F... 'lirobleml Involved in t 0 Integration of Agronovlo and Fconomlfl Methodoloa 163 in “oonomla 0: Elma 4xner1fieuts', (in) £34.13}. 1;; Lo, fina'". 1;. QI'“, 3 362:. JO T0, Lildl‘eth' 0. Ga. wtill er Innovaticna and Leenurca Ur , The laws 3:5qu LOLLbbB 15361113, LI mu, 1(11’Ffli35,73‘£.pt8!' 9.0. Tintnsr, Gerhard "Signifi canoe Qasta in Production Function Research“ (in) 1413233333 E. 0.. J04JISOJ 8% La. EFT-'51“, Lo 3., :WAQO'PmQ 'ggggngtivitz Regurns £0 Sc gleA_and Farm 9;;§,W1ne Iowa 3i1£¢ Galiage ireas, Axes, 'Qia. 33535, .2flpter 14. ‘ (b) Agtioleg En Pgrgodioal§.- Ready, 9.. 0., Pesek, J. '1‘... ”A Fertilizer Production Surfaoo with Specification of Ecunomio Uptima for Corn Grown on Cnloaranus Ila 911% Loan', qurnelflo: Farm Ecenomggg, Volume 35, August 1954. , p," . 42.2:3—4853. Heady, E. Co, 3383615., J. 1:". 31m1m9330~3 31:35:30,136 Bur-face. and 9oonomia aptimq 1n Fartiiizsr Use“, Research 3311119511} 42"“ :L fi'"'rficus. .411”:- 11 37.7212 :32'21212'238 3.9.t2fiion [will L31‘9q‘tr) 103:2: £31288, 1043.19.35. ‘ ' " ' Hearly, E. 0., Shraier, W. 3., “The Interrelationships of Agronomy and Loanomica 1n Research.an. 9990mm 3n13tionl to Farmers“, Av onom Journal, Volume Vb, Octo‘ber’lgfia, pgoégfi-bog. 93 Johnson, G. L., “Discussion: roonomio Implications of Agricultural 2xper1ment3fl Yoswnfil of Farm Egan0£103L Volume 39, 93v 1957, pp. 3 u-uui. Knetsch, J. L., Robertson, L. 3., Sundqulst, V. 8., “.2 Genomic Consideratlona in 3011 Fartillty Zesexrch'. Re.r1ntad from ”lnrtarlv Pulletln, of t2e '1oh_” Agricultural 1/13r1munt ntaticn. niohlgan 9t3ta University, rhat Lansing, Velume 59, Ho 1. pp. 10"16,Au£§u8t 1’} 560 Mason, David 0., “Statistical Problems of Joint finscrrch“, Journal of Farm Economics. Volume 39, May lIJV, bp- LPG-VBI. Trant G. 1., “Inplioatlons 0f Calculated Economic Optima 1n the Cauca Valley, Colombia, b. A.“ , Journ: 1 ct Farm 9oononiqg, Volume XL, February 1?58, pp.‘1 23-135. (0) Theaeg.- Knetsoh. J. L., “anthoflologioal Procedures and Applications for Incorporating Economic Cnnsideratlons into Fertilizer Recommendations”, unpu'nlished Haste? of science Thesis, Department of Agricultural Economics 91031; an State Universlty, East Lanaing,1 10.1ban,1508. Buniquist, V. 3., ”An Boanomio Analysis of flame Controlled Input-Output Fertilizer prerluants 1n licn1ran“, unpublished Ph.D. Tnesis, Dennrtment of Agricultural Economics, 910-13 33a State University, East Lansing, 1' 103313.: an. 1957. F3053”; .‘?SE OELY é? '75 - f; 1900 “fiAT': riff?" 7" 2:51! M'Wflifilflfilflflflifltfiflflfliflfiifllfilflifll‘lfif“ 7 8896