AN EVALUATION OF THE EFFECT OIf THE DIILON RDUND ON THE UNIT VALUE/IND WINNIE 0F ‘ UNITED STATES IMPORTS {IND EXPORTS - Thesis for the Degree of Ph. D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY ROBERT GOODMAN 1970 ”4694‘“ I LIBRARY ‘ 5’ Michigan brat: University This is to certify that the thesis entitled An Evaluation of the Effect of the Dillion Round on the Unit Vaiue and Volume of United States Imports and Exports presented by Robert Goodman has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Economics ,I-1'70“”r’fi/L7Z‘Jla4~ Wtw Major professor / 5‘ I § . Date/lint" 2Z5 /7éi 0-169 ABSTRACT AN EVALUATION OF THE EFFECT OF THE DILLON ROUND ON THE UNIT VALUE AND VOLUME OF UNITED STATES IWPORTS AND EXPORTS By Robert Goodman The objective of this investigation is to measure the effects of multilateral tariff reductions on the foreign trade sector of the American economy. In addi- tion to yielding figures on price and quantity changes of total exports and imports, the study is disaggregated into several commodity groups, permitting us to observe differential effects of tariff changes between groups which are subject to different elasticities. A comparison of average price and quantity trends between products subject to tariff reductions and closely related commodities not receiving concessions reveals the effect of tariff liberalization on the unit value and volume of United States' imports. Least—squares regres— sion analysis is used to develop demand functions in order to determine the "tariff sensitivity" of United States' exports. Furthermore, a measure of the net effect of the 1960-61 Tariff Conference on the United States' terms of trade is constructed, and estimates are made of the welfare and employment effects resulting from these negotiations. The results indicate that, while certain commodity categories were significantly affected by the reduction of tariff barriers, in the aggregate, the tariff con- cessions negotiated at the Dillon Round had a relatively minor effect on the American economy. AN EVALUATION OF THE EFFECT OF THE DILLON ROUND ON THE UNIT VALUE AND VOLUME OF UNITED STATES IMPORTS AND EXPORTS By Robert Goodman A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1970 562.725” 7—4-70 t/ Copyright by Robert Goodman 1970 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS First, I would like to express my gratitude for the valuable criticism and fruitful suggestions of my advisors: Professor Mordechai E. Kreinin, Professor Charles P. Larrowe and Professor Jan Kmenta. I also must thank Dr. Peter Lloyd, who made many helpful comments on the original draft of this thesis. I am also indebted to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which, in addition to granting me a leave of absence, provided all the facilities and clerical help needed to complete the dissertation. In addition, I must thank the patient and dedicated typist who struggled through the many drafts of the work, Miss Janet Huzil. Finally, I would like to thank my wife, Meri, whose encouragement was a source of constant inspiration. The responsibility for all the errors and, hope- fully, some of the valid contributions are my own. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . v Chapter I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 II. UNITED STATES COMMERCIAL POLICY . . . . . 3 The Trade Agreements Program . . . . . . 3 The 1958 Extension 7 The "Dillon" Round . ll . The Dillon Round and the European Economic Community . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 III. RECENT STUDIES OF PAST NEGOTIATIONS . . . . 20 IV. METHODOLOGY AND EMPIRICAL PROCEDURE . . . . 39 United States Imports . . . . . . . . 39 United States Exports . . . . . . . . 52 Demand Factors . . . . . . . . . . 52 Supply Factors . . . . . . 53 Specification of Export Function . . . . 5A Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 V. THE EFFECT OF THE DILLON ROUND ON UNITED STATES IMPORTS . . . . . . . . . . . 66 VI. THE EFFECT OF THE DILLON ROUND ON UNITED STATES EXPORTS . . . . . . . . . . . 81 Summary--The Effects of the Dillon Round on United States Trade . . . . . . . . . 87 VII. THE EFFECT ON THE DILLON ROUND ON THE DOMESTIC ECONOMY . . . . . . . . . . 91 Static Welfare Effect . . . . . . . . . 91 The Terms of Trade . . . . . . . . . . 102 Employment Effect . . . . . . . . . . 108 iii Chapter VIII. APPENDIX A APPENDIX B BIBLIOGRAPHY SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS iv 113 125 129 ISA LIST OF TABLES Table l. U.S. Imports in 1960 from Countries Negotiating with U.S. in the Reciprocal Phase of the 1960—61 Tariff Conference . . . . . . . . 2. Trade with the U.S. of Countries from which Direct Concessions were Obtained in the 1960-61 Tariff Conference . . . . . . . . . . 3. Imports, Dutiable and Free, by Economic Classes, 19147, 1953) 1956 o o o o o o o o o o A. Index of Volume of Imports into the United States of Products Whose Tariffs were Reduced by the Torquay Agreement, of Similar Products with no Tariff Reductions, and All Finished Manufactured Imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5. Price and Quantity Changes of Imported Commodities A. Between 1954 and 1956 B. Between 1955 and 1959 . . . . . . . . . . . 6. Nominal and Effective Tariff Rates, by Country, 1962 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7. The Effects of Tariff Concessions on the Prices and Volume of United States Imports . . . 8. Test of Significance of Observed Differences Between the Means of the Tariff—Reduced Group and the Non-Reduced Group--All Commodities 9. Test of Significance of Observed Difference Between the Means of the Tariff-Reduced Groups and the Non-Reduced Groups--By Commodity Groups . . . . . . . . . . . 10. Commodity Groups Experiencing Major Increases in Imports as a Consequence of the Dillon Round . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 11. 12. 13. 1“. Summary of Equations for U.S. Exports by Commodity and Destination 82 The Effect of Tariff Concessions on the Volume of United States Exports . . . . . . . . . 88 Changes in United States Industrial Trade as a Result of the 1960—61 Negotiations . . . . 89 Employment Effects of the 1960-61 Tariff Conference . . . . . . . . . lll vi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION It has long been recognized in the pure theory of international trade that the complete elimination of trade barriers would lead to the optimization of world welfare to the benefit of all. However, while theoret- ically appealing, nationalistic self-interest severely hampered efforts to reduce restrictions on trade flows. Only with the ratification of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade in 1947, were the ground rules laid for meaningful negotiations between interested parties on the reduction and elimination of impediments to free trade. Thus, multilateral collective bargaining was seen as a feasible and practical approach to this complex task. Under its auspices six rounds of tariff negotia- tion have taken place--Geneva, 1947; Annecy, 1949; Torquay, 1951: and Geneva, in 1956, 1960-61; and 1964-67. Under the authorization of the 1958 extension of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act, the United States negotiated tariff concessions at the 1960-61 Geneva Conference (Dillon Round). In this thesis, I will R.) investigate the effect of multilateral tariff reduction on the unit value and volume of the imports and exports of the United States, and construct a measure of the gain or loss in the United States terms of trade. As a second step, I shall estimate the net change in welfare and employment resulting from these negotiations. Chapter II will place the 1958 extension of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act in historical perspective. An in—depth discussion of the Act itself will then provide an adequate background in which to View the 1960-61 negotiations. In Chapter III, I will review and criti- cally examine previous studies concerning similar negotiations. The method and empirical procedure employed in this thesis will be discussed in Chapter IV. Chapters V and VI will present the results of the investigation by considering the impact of the 1960—61 negotiations upon U.S. imports and exports, respectively. Chapter VII will be reserved for an examination of the effects of the Dillon Round with respect to welfare, the terms of trade and employment. Chapter VIII will explore the implications of our findings for future U.S. tariff policy. CHAPTER II UNITED STATES COMMERCIAL POLICY The Trade Agreements Program Since the Passage of the Tariff Act of 1930, it has been the policy of the United States Congress to enter into trade agreements with foreign governments. The original Act limited this authority to a period of three years from June 12, 1934, the date of enactment of the Act. Known as the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act it authorized the President to sign commercial agreements with other nations reducing existing U.S. duties by as much as 50 per cent in exchange for parallel concessions. Subsequently, the Act was amended, extending the authority of the President as it became clear to the Congress that only through healthy international relations could a sound domestic economy be maintained.1 1The original Act limited the authority of the President to enter into foreign trade agreements to a period of three years from June 12, 1934, the date of enactment of the Act (48 Stat. 943). The President's authority to enter into foreign trade agreements has been extended from time to time as follows: Pub. Res. No. 10, 75th Cong., for 3 years from June 1937 (50 Stat. 24); Pub. Res. No. 61, 76th Cong., for 3 years from June 12, 1940 (54 Stat. 107); Pub. Law 66, 78th Cong., for 2 years from June 12, 1943 (57 Stat. 125); In no sense, however, did the Reciprocal Trade Agreement program contemplate the complete abandonment of protection. In 1948, the 80th Congress inserted the peril-point requirement into the Act. While this clause was eliminated in 1949, it was restored in 1951, and the escape clause was also written into law. Under the peril-point provision, the United States Tariff Commission was required to investigate and determine, in advance of any negotiation, the limit of "safe bargaining" beyond which tariff reduction may imperil any branch of home industry. Duties were not to be cut if such action threatened serious injury to American industry. Moreover, the escape clause required an upward adjustment of a duty reduced as a result of negotiations if serious injury were shown to have resulted from that reduction. Upon a finding by the Tariff Commission that a product on which a concession had been granted was being imported in such increased quantities, either absolute or relative, as to cause or threaten serious injury to the competing domestic industry, the President was authorized to Pub. Law 130, 79th Cong., for 3 years from June 12, 1945 (59 Stat. 410): Pub. Law 307, 8lst Cong., for 3 years from June 12, 1948 (63 Stat. 697); Pub. Law 50, 82nd Cong., for 2 years from June 12, 1951 (65 Stat. 72); Pub. Law 215, 83rd Cong., for 1 year from June 12, 1953 (67 Stat. 472); Pub. Law 464, 83rd Cong., for 1 year from June 12, 1954 (68 Stat. 360): Pub. Law 86, 84th Cong., from June 12, 1955 until the close of June 30, 1958 (69 Stat. 162); and Pub. Law 85-686, until the close of June 1962 (72 Stat. 673). In July, 1962, the Trade Expansion Act renewed this authority for 5 years until June, 1967- withdraw or modify the concession. Thus, protection could be restored even though the output of American industry was growing, provided only that imports were growing faster. Since 1949 the number of applications per year has ranged between six and twelve. In 1960 seventeen cases were initiated eight of which were the outgrowth of peril-point investigations.2 Later extensions of the Trade Agreement Act went further by defining an industry as the producers of single products, thus making it relatively simple for a multiple product industry to claim injury even though increased foreign competition was limited to only one of its several products.3 Reinforcing the protectionist policy embodied in the escape clause was the insertion of the National Security clause in the 1955 extension of the Act. The withdrawal or modification of a concession was authorized when such a concession induced increases in imports in such quantitities so as to threaten the national security. 2See, I. Kravis, "Trade Agreement Excape Clause", American Economic Review, June, 1954; and w. B. Kelly, "The Expanded Trade Agreements Escape Clause, 1955-61," Journal of Political Economy, February, 1962. 3The 1955 act (69 Stat. 162) defines the "domestic industry" as "that portion or subdivision of the producing organizations manufacturing, assembling, processing, extracting, growing, or otherwise producing like or directly competitive products or articles in commercial quantities." Thus, the Tariff Commission was to confine its investigations to that part of the operations of multiproduct producers who make a particular article. The law (National Defense Amendment of 1955) however, defines almost any adverse effect on economic welfare, such as increased unemployment, loss of government revenues, or loss of skills or investment, as consti- tuting impairment of national security. In sum, the Trade Agreements Act and related legislation sought to expand American exports by an exchange of concessions, but it continued to afford effective protection for most domestic industries encountering foreign competition. Most importantly, U.S. legislation refused to tolerate injury to domestic producers from such competition. Any such injury, real or threatened, was not to be tolerated. These two philosophies, namely trade liberalization and "no injury" to domestic industry appear to be incompatible with the concept of economic efficiency, if indeed this is the goal to be sought through tariff negotiations. However, if political considerations were the prime movers of U.S. commercial policy during this period, they become quite consistent.“ “The dual nature of U.S. tariff policy has been stressed by D. Humphrey, American Imports, New York, 1955; p. 107, and M. E. Kreinin, Alternative Commercial Policies, MSU International Business and Economic Studies, 1957; p. 18. The 1958 Extension This thesis focuses on the 1958 extension of this legislation, since it was under its authority that the United States negotiated the trade agreements at Geneva in 1960-61. With the expiration of the 1955 extension of the Act, the Administration asked for a five-year extension coupled with tariff-cutting authority of 25 per cent (or, alternatively, three percentage points). This decision was heavily influenced by the emergence of the European Economic Community (EEC). The integration schedule called for the reduction of inter-community tariff rates by 30 per cent by 1963. It was feared that with the lowered rates among the Six, the United States would be put at a distinct competitive disadvantage, affecting some $3.2 billions of American goods, or almost 20 per cent of all United States exports if we use the 1957 figures. At the same time that the six countries lowered their internal barriers to each other, by 30 per cent, they were to begin erecting a common external tariff (CXT) to outside products.5 As Senator Douglas saw it, "the only way American exports can compete in this market is if the United States has the authority to negotiate to get their common external tariff lowered 5The proposed CXT was to be an arithmetic average of the tariffs of the six countries existing prior to January 1, 1958. at the same relative rate as the internal rates are lowered, or by 30 per cent in the first four to five-year period.6 The first stage of the CXT was due to go into effect on January 1, 1962. Negotiations between the United States and the Common Market were to begin in late 1960. If Congress acted favorably on the President's request, the full 25 per cent authority could be used since no part would have expired. Furthermore, this authority, with its carry-over provision which permitted tariff cuts negotiated during the five—year period to be put into effect any time after that period, would have put the United States close to parity with the 30 per cent authority of the Common Market. On August 20, 1958, following extensive hearings before the House Ways and Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee, Congress passed the Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1958. However, this Act fell short of the Administration's request. Under its auspices the President was authorized to negotiate trade agreements with foreign governments for a period of four years from the close of June 30, 1958 through June 30, 1962. Under this legislation, any rate as of July 1, 1958 could be reduced in not more than four annual stages by 685th Congress Second Session, Senate Report 1838, July 15, 1958. one of the following three alternatives: (1) by not more than 20 per cent; (2) by not more than two percentage points or its equivalent in the case of specific duties; or (3) down to 50 per cent ad yglgrgm. The latter two alternatives are significant in cases where the rates prevailing in 1958 were below 10 per cent or above 62.5 per cent respectively. In the case of any duty to which (1) or (2) applied, no amount of decrease becoming initially effective at one time was to exceed 10 per cent or 1 percentage point ad valorem of the rate of duty existing on July 1, 1958, respectively. Where the decrease was down to 50 per cent gg valorem the decrease was not to exceed one-third of the total amount of the reduction under ' the foreign trade agreement. The new legislation strengthened the "no injury" concept (i.e., tariff liberalization with a minimum of injury to domestic industry) by extending the time period for peril-point investigations from 120 days to six months. Peril point studies were to be made prior to negotiations for new trade agreements and provide the President with factual information and recommendations regarding the level below which the tariff rate on each product could not be lowered without causing or threatening injury to the industries producing them. The two month extension was seen as an aid to the Tariff Commission insofar as it enabled the Commission to make more complete 10 investigations of a large number of commodities at one time. To further protect domestic industries and to facilitate peril point inquiries, the Tariff Commission was given the power to subpoena any and all documents or records pertinent to the subject matter under investigation. In the event that the peril point investigation revealed that an industry was threatened by import of a product which had been the subject of a trade agreement, that industry could file for immediate escape-clause relief. This relief could be in the form of an increase in the duty or an additional import restriction. Furthermore, by allowing a narrow definition of the market, the legislation permitted an industry to apply for escape-clause relief by showing only that a small segment of the industry had sustained injury. The National Security Amendment was modified so that no action would be taken to reduce the duty on an article if the President found that such a reduction would threaten to impair the national security. This strengthened the existing law which required that no action be taken which would endanger domestic production needed for projected national defense requirements. Thus the 1958 extension, while authorizing further tariff liberalization, still incorporated the protec- tionist philosophy found in previous extensions of the Act. 11 In light of this new authority, it clearly remained to be seen whether the United States, armed with the bargining weapons provided by the new extension of the Trade Agreements Act, could secure for itself a larger share of the European Market. The "Dillon" Round On September 1, 1960, the United States commenced trade negotiations with the European Economic Community (EEC) and 17 other countries7 with the purpose of further liberalization of foreign commerce between the contracting parties. The concessions granted by the United States were in return for reciprocal concessions obtained from the members of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Under GATT, all concessions are initially negotiated bilaterally directly with individual countries, normally the principal supplier, or with a customs union acting as a unit on behalf of its member governments, but the concessions are extended multilaterally to the other contracting parties. The U.S. also adheres to the most-favored nation's principal, whereby it accords to other governments, not contracting parties to the GATT, those concessions granted to the principal suppliers. 7The contracting parties were: Israel, Portugal, Pakistan, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Finland, New Zealand, Norway, Peru, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, Haiti, India, Japan and Cambodia. 12 Because of the scope and complexity of the nego- tiations, the conference, the fifth held for the purpose of reducing tariffs on a multilateral basis, was organized in two phases. The first phase, which com- menced on September 1, 1960, was concerned principally with negotiations held under the provisions of Article XXIV:6 of the GATT with the six EEC countries negotiating During the second, or reciprocal phase, which began on May 29, 1961, the United States completed an exchange of new tariff concessions among interested countries. Concessions granted by the United States at the 1960-61 Tariff Conference were made on products selected from 89 of the 99 commodity subgroups of imports (Schedule A nos. 010—990).9 Imports of products within the subgroups receiving concessions totalled $1,827.1 million in 1960. Almost half of this trade ($876.5 8The rules of the General Agreement relating to customs unions and free-trade areas are contained in Article XXIV. It sets out a series of rules designed to ensure that a customs union shall in effect lead to the reduction and elimination of barriers within the area without raising new barriers to trade with the out- side world. It also contains the conditions under which a customs union is accepted as an exception to the most— favored-nation clause. 9The ten commodity subgroups in which no concessions were granted were edible animals; animal oil and fats edible; cocoa, coffee and tea; unmanufactured cotton; cotton semi-manufactures; coal and related fuels; petro- leum and products; lead and manufactures; tin, zinc and manufactures. 13 million) consisted of machinery and vehicles. About 11 per cent ($194.4 million) was in vegetable foods and beverages, and about 9 per cent ($170.9 million) was in metals and manufactures other than machinery and vehicles. Tariff reductions were also granted on products from the following commodity groups: Textile fibers and products, $97.4 million; non-metallic minerals, $97.1 million; chemicals and related products, $61.8 million; inedible vegetable products other than fiber and wood, $50.5 million; wood and paper products, $48.8 million; edible animals and edible animal products, $44.4 million; inedible animals and inedible animal products, $43.5 million; and miscellaneous products, $141.7 million. Thus about 20 per cent of the total dutiable imports of the United States in 1960 were the subject of tariff concessions. These concessions involved almost 1,200 statistical classes of products (Schedule A groups 0-9). The duty reductions were primarily in the magnitude of 20 per cent. However, for those products for which existing duties were equal to 10 per cent ad valorem, or less, or greater than 62.5 per cent ad valorem, reductions of more than 20 per cent were realized. The larger reduc- tions resulted from the exercise of the authority to lower duties by 2 percentage points, or, in the case of 14 duties in excess of 62.5 per cent ad valorem, down to 50 per cent. Of the concessions granted by the U.S., (See Table I), imports from the country of direct negotiation accounted for $1,224.8 million of the total from all sources. As a consequence of the United States' adherence to the most favored-nation's principal, another $490.6 million in concessions were granted. Nearly two-thirds of the items were negotiated directly with the EEC. The direct concessions granted to the EEC covered imports totaling $794.8 million in 1960, a volume of trade which was almost four times that involved in any other bilateral negotiations concluded at the conference. Concessions granted to the U.K. and Canada ranked second and third, respectively. In return for concessions granted, the U.S. was the recipient of tariff reductions on a wide range of com- modities, totaling $2,764.5 million of exports. Thus, about 25 per cent of total U.S. exports to the GATT nations in 1960 were subject to a downward revision in tariff rates. The Dillon Round and the European Economic Communiay The Treaty of Rome, which established the Common Market, provides that the tariffs of the EEC Member TABLE 1.--U.S. imports in 1960 from countries negotiating with U.S. 15 reciprocal phase 1960-61 Tariff Conference. Imports of Products on Which Concessions Were Granted and Imports of All Products (Millions of dollars) 3': .= z = 3... ' ‘4 T. ‘1 7". 1': :31 .= =1: :———— :2: Z: =— in the Imports from country named in column 1 Products on which Negotiating concessions were granted All products Country In negoti- In negoti- ation with ation with In “11 , countrv in other negotia— Dutiable Free Total column 1 countries tions Total 1,224.8 400.6 1,715 4 5,801 3 2,697.0 8,588.3 EEC 794.8 30.4 825.2 2,003 1 255.4 258.5 Austria 10.2 4.4 14 f 48 7 9 49.6 Cambodia -- -- -- a 6.6 6.6 Canada 64.5 71.0 135.9 1,204 2 1,708.0 2,912.2 Denmark 1.3 10.8 12 l 79 3 19.1 98.4 Finland 2.8 1.3 4 1 19 8 32.3 52.1 Haiti .6 .3 9 6.5 11.1 17.6 India 51.3 2.8 54.1 161.6 68.4 230.0 Israel 17.5 1.3 18.8 24 . 3.3 27.3 Japan 18.5 54.1 72.6 1,046 7 79.8 1,126.5 New Zealand 11.6 b 11.6 59.4 57.6 117.0 Norway 5.u 3.0 8.4 66.3 ' 21.u 87.7 Pakistan 0 d e 9. 26.7 36.0 Peru 6.0 f 6.0 67.2 101.7 168.9 Portugalg 9.2 1.6 10.8 28.9 8.6 37.5 Sweden 12.6 43.2 55.8 120.4 50 0 170.4 Switzerland 17.1 23.2 40.3 166.3 29.7 196.0 United Kingdom 201.4 242.8 444.2 779.6 216.4 996.0 as 2,000. b$34,000. c$141,000. d$24,000. e$65,000. f$29,000. gIncludes Azores and Madeira Islands. * U.S. Source: import figures are valued f.o.b. Volume III, p. Department of State, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Analysis of United States Negotiations, 152. 16 States shall be gradually replaced by a common external tariff by January 1, 1970, and in any event not later than January 1, 1973. On January 1, 1961, the Member States took the first in a series of scheduled moves to align their individual tariffs with that of the common tariff. This first alignment entailed the abandonment of the individual schedules of tariff concessions previously contracted in GATT with the contracting parties, including the United States. The GATT permits contracting parties to establish a customs union provided that the new external tariff is, on the whole, not higher than the general incidence of the duties applied by the constituent members prior to the formation of the union. The common external tariff which the EEC published in 1960 was based largely on the arithmetic average of the national rates of the Member States, although some rates were negotiated internally among the Six. The GATT recognizes that a customs union neces— sarily involves an alignment of existing individual national tariffs with a new common tariff; hence some duties may go up, others down, while some may remain the same. If rates are increased on those products for which Member States had previously undertaken commitments against increases, the GATT requires the customs union to compensate those contracting parties having rights 17 either as initial negotiators of the commitment, or as principal suppliers of the commodities involved. The GATT requires that the calculation of compensation take account of duties which are being reduced from previous levels as well as the bound duties being increased. The criteria and procedures for these negotiations are set forth in Article XXIV:6. The U.S. objective in the Article XXIV:6 nego- tiations was to obtain a set of concessions in the CXT which, in terms of trade coverage and duty level, would satisfactorily replace all of the concessions which the U.S. had had with the six separate countries prior to the formation of the EEC customs union. Of the 2,900 tariff positions in the new common tariff, the U.S. identified 1,100 where it potentially had claims for compensation under Article XXIV:6 either as initial negotiator or major supplier. As a result of these negotiations, nearly three—fourths of the direct con— cessions obtained by the United States were at rates equivalent to or below duty rates which the individual Member states had previously applied. Table 2 summarizes the concessions obtained by the U.S. as a result of the 1960-61 Conference. The amount of trade dealt with in both phases of the 1960-61 Conference was sizeable, cumulatively amounting to more than $4.6 billion of U.S. exports TABLE 2.--Trade with the U.S. 18 of countries from which direct concessions were obtained in the 1960-61 Tariff Conference. (U.S. $1 million-1960) Imports from the U.S. of Products on which U.S. Total Imports Country Obtained Direct from U.S. Concessions Total 2,764.5 12,037.6 EEC (XXIV:6 Negotiationsc) 1,200.0 -- EEC (Reciprocal Negotiations) 1,000.0 3,400.0 Austria 7.6 80.0 Cambodia 1.1 8.9 Canada 75.1 3,632.7 Denmark 17.2 108.7 Finland 4.6 56.3 Haiti a 25.1 India 43.6 608.6 Israel 21.8 118.4 Japan 23.4 1,554.2 New Zealand 4.5 74.6 Norway 20.8 89.1 Pakistan b 168.8 Peru 6.7 142.1 Portugal 8.9 38.4 Sweden 9.6 298.8 Switzerland 19.6 246.5 United Kingdom 300.0 1,386.4 rights in Member States' a$46,000. b$79,000. CThe Commission of the EEC negotiated with the United States and other contracting parties having contractual tariff concessions that had to be modified as the Six started moving toward the Common Exter- nal Tariff. Volume I, p. *Imports from the U.S. are reported c.i.f. Source: Department of State, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Analysis of United States Neggtiations, 106. l9 and imports in 1960. Thus, the negotiations affected almost 14 per cent of total U.S. trade in 1960 and more than 20 per cent of the total trade conducted with the participating members of GATT.1O loTotal U.S. trade (imports and exports) of merchandise for consumption amounted to $34.9 billion in 1960. Trade with the contracting parties in the 1960-61 negotiations amounted to approximately $20.6 billion in 1960. U.S. Department of Commerce. CHAPTER III RECENT STUDIES OF PAST NEGOTIATIONS Before analyzing the economic consequences of the tariff reductions negotiated in the Dillon Round, a discussion of previous investigations pertaining to recent tariff conferences will provide a basis for comparing our results to those obtained by other inves- tigators. A comparison between volume changes of dutiable and duty-free imports has frequently been taken as an index of the effectiveness of tariff changes. In a study prepared for the House Ways and Means Committee,11 Piquet found that in four out of five economic classes, imports of dutiable commodities exhibited larger per- centage growth rates between 1947 and 1956 than did duty-free items (See Table 3). This period saw trade agreement activity at the Geneva, Annecy, and Torquay Conferences. These results lead him to the conclusion that "reduction of tariffs by trade agreement have been moderately effective." His technique implicitly assumes llSee Foreign Trade Policy, Compendium of Papers, Subcommittee, on Foreign Trade Policy of the House Committee on Ways and Means, 85th Congress, 2nd Session, Washington, 1958. 20 21 .wmma “commCHnmmz .COfimmom cam .mmmhwcoo cpmw .mmmmdm no ezficcoQEoo “moflaom mpmpe cwfiopom =.mps0QEH .m.D can mCOHpospmm Manama: .posvflm .m ”meadow H.0m + omm.e omm.m ems.m m.mma+ Ham.e mmm.s mam.m Hmpoe H.mmfi+ ssfi.fi was 0mm o.omm+ smo.m sfim.a mm: masseuse Iaeaz eoenacaa m.ss I mms.H eos.H mmm s.msm+ sem.a mam.a om: monaaomeaeszHEom a.sa I mm meg am m.sm + mmH.H mam nae nacapneoos bondhowmscmz m.eos+ mam.fi sam.fi mam m.sm + mam mom wma nameHe< new mmmsumpoom bongo e.ms + mms.fi ea:.a H@H.H m.mmfi+ Hmm.H sHH.H mam namanosmz tease 331;? mm? mm? 33 3.3132 mm? mmmfi 32 mwmwmmmwom mugoQEH oosm owmwmmmmom mpLOQEH oanmfiusa mmmao oHEocoom .emaH .mmma .asaa Annmaaoo mo mcofiHHHE cw mpLOQEHv .mmmmmflo OHEOCOOm an .omsm ocm mapmfiuso .npsoasHsu.m mamas 22 that in the absence of tariff reductions, for each of the five classes studied, the two lists (dutiable and free) would exhibit parallel trends in growth. Furthermore, for his method to be valid, each list must contain the same commodities in 1956 as in 1947. In this connection, he must account for the possibility of the transfer of a free item to the dutiable list during this period, since such a shift would imply growth in dutiable imports even in the absence of tariff reductions. Indeed, such a shift would reflect an increase in protection. As a further complication, domestic price changes during this period may not have affected both groups equally. Thus, the differential impact of inflation on the two groups may distort his findings. He makes no attempt to isolate the effect of the tariff reductions on import prices, nor does he investigate the effectiveness of multilateral tariff negotiations in stimulating United States exports. Lawrence B. Krause examined the relationship between tariff concessions negotiated at Torquay in 1951 and the subsequent increase in the volume of U.S. imports.l2 Since the method he employed is similar to the one used in this thesis, a detailed decription of the procedure is reserved for a later chapter. Basically, 12Lawrence B. Krause, "United States Imports and the Tariff," American Economic Review, Proceedings, May, 1959, pp. 542-51. 23 his work is an analysis of the behavior of two groups of commodities. One group contains many of the manu- factured products on which the U.S. import tariff was reduced at the Torquay negotiation, while the other is comprised of similar manufactured products on which tariffs were 222 changed during these negotiations. These groups were made comparable by selecting the non-reduced group in such a way as to equate it with respect to commodity composition and the average value of imports of the reduced group. The analysis concerns the dollar volume of U.S. imports of the two groups in the years 1952 to 1956, while the years 1949—51 were used as a base. In the absence of tariff reductions, and except for possible strong substitution effects between the two groups, these two groups would be expected to exhibit parallel changes in growth. Thus, a priori, an index reflecting the volume of imports for the reduced group should exceed that of the non- reduced group for all years subsequent to the tariff reductions. His results are presented in Table 4. A student's "T" test reveals that although the volume of imports of both groups rose sharply in this period, the difference between them was statistically insig- nificant. He then divided the reduced items according to the amount of the 1951 tariff reduction and to the tariff levels after the reduction. It is particularly 24 TABLE 4.--Index of volume of imports into the United States of products whose tariffs were reduced by the Torquay Agreement, of similar products with no tariff reductions, and of all finished manufactured imports. (1949-51 Average = 100) Reduced Non-reduced All Finished Manufactures 1949-51 100.0 100.0 100.0 1952 124.3 129.2 124.8 1953 182.7 165.5 133.1 1954 162.5 157.1 133.8 1955 197.0 206.1 160.9 1956 241.2 230.7 194.7 Source: L. B. Krause, "United States Imports and the Tariff,‘' American Economic Review, Proceedings, May, 1959; p. 543. 25 interesting to note that volume increases were greatest for those commodities where tariff rates had been reduced by 30 per cent or more. The general conclusion of the statistical analysis is that the tariff reductions negotiated at Torquay in 1951 cannot be regarded as a significant factor in the import increases that followed. In explaining his findings, Krause suggests that political as well as economic considerations may explain why the Torquay negotiations had no significant effect in increasing imports. Among the economic considerations he lists the effect of price increases in reducing the protectiveness of tariffs levied in the form of specific rather than ad valorem duties, the nature of import demand, (i.e., the response of imports to changes in tariff rates) and the incentives for foreign producers to supply increased U.S. import demand. When import prices increase, the ad valorem equivalent of specific duties declines, as does the restrictive effect of the tariff. Since this will tend to stimulate imports of both the reduced and control groups, the impact of tariff reduction becomes more difficult to ascertain. With regard to import demand, Krause postulates that import demand is more than proportionately responsive to large tariff changes. He finds that increases in trade were much greater for items whose tariffs were reduced by more than 30 per cent, than for items receiving reductions 26 of less than 30 per cent. Since more than 90 per cent of the base value of concessions were in the latter category, he concludes that no significant increase in trade could be demonstrated in part because tariff reductions on major commodities were insufficient to induce substantial increases in imports. Among the political considerations, he discusses the "no injury" concept as it applied to permitted tariff reductions, as well as the tariff structure as it existed in 1951. With regard to the latter, he points out that tariff reduction may not have been adequate to remove the "excess" protection enjoyed by the commodities in the reduced group.13 Thus, he con- cludes, tariff levels, rather than changes are of prime importance. However, Kreininlu suggests that, since 1951, cumulative tariff reductions have lowered U.S. tariffs to a level where further reduction may induce significant changes in U.S. imports. l3For empirical evidence of the restrictive nature of the U.S. tariff see M. E. Kreinin, "On the Restrictive Effect of the Tariff--A Note on the Use of the Balassa Index", The Manchester School, January, 1966, pp. 75-80. lL‘Mordechai E. Kreinin, "Effect of Tariff Changes on the Prices and Volume of Imports," The American Economic Review, June, 1961, p. 320. The realized average duty on dutiable imports was 47 per cent in 1934 and 14 per cent in 1949. As a result of further tariff reductions, the average duty declined to 12 per cent in 1952. Kreinin's results suggest that the average duty may have been reduced by as much as 15 per cent (down to 11.2 per cent ad valorem) as a result of the 1956 negotiations. 27 Krause does not take into consideration the effect of priCe Changes which may have occurred in the two groups of commodities, but rather assumes that import prices reflected fully the tariff changes in the reduced group. If imports are a relatively small part of total consumption, it is possible for a large increase in imports to occur with little decline in import price. The benefit of the tariff reduction would accrue to the foreign suppliers in the form of higher export prices. The subsequent increase in import volume would occur as foreign suppliers, having absorbed the tariff concessions, become capable of more vigorous price competition with import-competing products. Although Krause finds no significant difference between the means of his two samples, this may be due in large part to the degree of aggregation of the two groups. The tariff elasticity of demand will vary directly with the degree of substitutability. While total imports are a small part of total consumption it is a relatively large share when compared to the shares of the individual commodity groups which comprise the total. Thus, it may be expected that the tariff elasticity of demand of separate commodity categories is larger than that for all commodities taken together. It may be, therefore, to our advantage to apply a test of statistical significance to each of these subgroups 28 as well as to the aggregates in order to more accurately evaluate the effectiveness of any reduction in duty level. Mordechai E. Kreinin, who recognized Krause's failure to take into account possible changes in prices, investigated data from the 1955 and 1956 GATT negotia- 15 The effects of a tariff reduction are shown as tions. taking place in four stages. The tariff reduction leads to a decrease in import prices and improved terms of trade for supplying nations. This price decline leads to an increase in the volume of U.S. imports and subsequently to a reduction in U.S. employment. The empirical technique is essentially the same as that used by Krause but differs in so far as Kreinin takes into account the changes in prices that attented the tariff cuts. His results are summarized in Tables 5 (A) and 5 (B). For the 1955 negotiations it was found that one- third of the benefit of the duty reductions was passed on to domestic consumers while two-thirds accrued to foreign suppliers in the form of higher export prices. The 1956 negotiations were much larger and extended over a longer period of time. Greater weight is given to these results since the reduced group was 14 times larger than that for 1955. The reduced group underwent 151818. 29 .mam .Q .HmoH secs: .zmfl>om oHEOCOom cmoflaoe< one :.mpLOQEH ho mESHo> pcm meowna m5» :0 mmwcmso umflpme no pomumm : .cflcflmsx .m Hmcooppoz "mopsom mw+ m.m+ adopo boosponcoz mam ms m.a om+ s.m+ aaoso oooaoem monzuomuscmz oozmficflm 2m+ :.m+ Qsopo nooznoccoz mum ms m.m ww+ o.m+ nacho pmozpom mmwpflpoeeoo HH< .mm a. an . -eICH arm mmoai. rmcfl 12m mmofl sterner LOpw QSOL C membflfiqwu esp Lo muLOQEH .n no osam> bmmgm>< : mm+ m.:| nzoso poozpmscor ea mm i.s am+ C.s+ aaoho eooaoom mmflfitxme wcflpsfioxm psallmmfipflpoeeoo HH< Nfl+ m.:| qzopo obozpbgco: Hm an n.o om+ m.a+ Qsoso nmospmm mmeHUoEEoo HH¢ Anpmflao: COAHHwEV pceo Ema uceo and unto Ema unto Led d;cfl can 2mmH dgflgmb mowga mmgmnm omoflga ugooxm Lou anono twosomm mpflpcmsc :fi mmcmco esp mo mpLOQEH uo.osflm> mmmgo>¢ (HO HCIQO Lmufi. mm eoaeoaemm cusses umma ocm :mm H Cmmzumm .mmfipfipoEEOU pcuLOQEH Mo mbmcmso zpfipcmso ocm oofipmll.m mqmm c< “mmflspczoo HmfigumSUCH CH cofipooposm mmfinmez .mmmmamm .m ”condom :.mm m.mm m.wH smash m.mH m.mH m.m cooozm m.sH m.wH m.HH poxsmz coEEoo m.mm m.sm m.mH shamans obese: 5.0H 0.0m m.HH mopmum popfica pcoaw>flsom ommso>< popcwfioz mmmso>< oouzwfioz humane Esomfics mmmwpme m>Hpoomwm. humane HmQHEoz .meaa .sbceaoo sb .ncems ceases bsabccccb och Hecasoznn.e mamas 50 His figures suggest that among these five areas Japan has the highest rate with respect to both nominal and effective duties, while the United Kingdom ranks second. The United States and the EEC are about even with the United States having a higher effective level and the EEC slightly higher in its level of nominal tariffs. At the opposite end of the scale is Sweden which has the lowest level of nominal as well as effective rates. One purpose of calculating effective protective rates is to obtain indications of the direction in which resources are pulled by the tariff structure. Effective rates determine, along with production substitution elasticities, the production effect of a tariff. On the other hand, nominal rates determine, together with expenditure substitution elasticities, the expenditure or consumption effect. It may therefore be both neces- sary and desireable to take into account the effective protective level of a tariff when considering the con- sequences of its reduction. However, this study will not employ effective tariff rates for several reasons. First of all, the effective level of protection has not been computed for Canada and several other countries which account for an important share of United States trade. Secondly, those estimates which are available 51 are not sufficiently disaggregated for our purposes. Many of the industrial products studied in this thesis enter as inputs in the production of other products. Thus a decrease in nominal tariff rates would lower effective protection by more than the change in nominal duties. In order to estimate the change in the effec- tive tariff structure it would be necessary to know the share of dutiable inputs used in the production of each commodity studied. Since this information is not available it is impossible to measure the change in the effective rates of protection. This problem is com- pounded when we realize the possibility of more than one input in the production process. 27 has suggested that in the course of Kreinin successive GATT negotiations manufactured goods (i.e., categories 5-8 SITC) were probably subject to larger tariff cuts than those on semi-finished or primary commodities. If his hypothesis is correct, changes in effective rates have exceeded changes in nominal rates. Therefore, it would seem that for the United States the use of nominal rates would impart an upward bias to the effect of tariff negotiations on trade flows. 27M. E. Kreinin, "'Price' vs. 'Tariff' Elasticities in International Trade--A Suggested Reconciliation," American Economic Review, Vol. LVII, September, 1967, pp. 891-894. 52 United States Exports Since tariff concessions granted to the United States differed from one trading partner to another, it will be necessary to evaluate their effect on the volume of exports on a country by country basis. Of the 23 members of the GATT participating in the 1960-61 Conference, the European Economic Community, Canada, and the United Kingdom accounted for approximately 93 per cent of the value of all concessions received by the United States.28 Thus, we will confine ourselves to investigating the effectiveness of tariff reductions in stimulating U.S. exports to these areas. Demand‘Factors The relationship between movements of domestic demand and imports accounts for the largest part of the variation in import volume. Imports may be seen as consisting of materials and semi-manufactures going into current production, imports of finished goods going into final demand for current use, and imports for inventory replenishment. Therefore, as the level of economic activity within an area increases, ceteris paribus, we would expect a rise in the volume of goods imported. 281h 1960, these areas accounted for 70 per cent of all U.S. exports of manufactured commodities. 53 Thus, if we are to explain variation in U.S. exports to a given area, it will be necessary to account for the influence of demand pressures within the country of destination. Because of the cyclical diversity of the demand for various products, complex relationships appear to govern the movements of total imports (U.S. exports) over the business cycle. The movement of various U.S. export categories is likely to diverge over the business cycle, with some categories, like exports of machinery and other manufactures, being far more cyclically sensitive than materials or foodstuffs. These phenomena may be caught empirically by estimating export functions separately for various product categories. Supply factors Relative price relationships may play a significant role in determining the flow of U.S. exports to a par- ticular area. a priori, one would expect movements in U.S. prices relative to the prices of domestically produced import-competing goods to be of prime impor- tance in the choice between these substitutes. Of equal importance is price competition from third country suppliers. Changes in U.S. prices vis a vis foreign sources of supply may also be expected to 54 be an important factor in determining the share of U.S. exports to a given market. Another factor which can be expected to influence trade flows, and the one to which we will direct our attention, is the level of tariffs. The imposition of a tariff creates a divergence between the price paid by the importer and that received by the exporter. Thus, a price decline resulting from a tariff reduction has a different supply effect as compared to one resulting from a lowering of the U.S. offer price. In the former case, the U.S. supplier will receive the same return per unit (or even higher if the entire tariff change is not passed on to the consumer), while in the latter one, he will receive less. This would lead one to expect that the quantity of goods exported would react differ- ently to an equal percentage change in the two elements. dpecification of the Export Function Our analysis will be conducted at the commodity group level (Schedule B commodity categories 3-9). The volume of U.S. exports of commodity group i to area j was taken from the following identity 3. J J J xi - 111(13i + Xi - E1) [1] 55 where Xi is the quantity of U.S. exports of commodities of the 1&8 commodity group, which were subject to tariff 29 reductions, to area j. u is the portion of domestic consumption of the i 1:2 commodity group provided by U.S. exports. Pi is the quantity of domestic production of category i in area j. E; is exports of category 1 commodities from area j. Solving for Xi we get ui J _ J J Xi - (Pi - Bi) [2] 1 - u 1 Practical considerations forced an alteration of the equation. It was felt that adjusting domestic production for exports would not greatly affect the var- iable Pg since area j exports of commodities imported from the United States in considerable amounts could be expected to be quite small in relation to total domestic production. Furthermore, since data for domestic production of various commodity groups by area was not readily obtainable, an index of overall industrial production (P3) (1960=100) for each area will be used. This index has performed well as a 29When referring to commodity group i we will only consider commodities within group i which have received tariff concessions. This procedure will minimize the risk of the dependent variable reflecting random varia- tions unrelated to tariff concessions. 56 proxy for economic activity and will be used in this investigation as an activity-demand variable.30 The ratio of the share of the 122 commodity group provided by U.S. exports to the share provided by domes- tic production (ui/l-ui), will be considered to be a function of the ratio of the U.S. export price in area j to the domestic wholesale price prevailing in area j, the ratio of U.S. wholesale prices of commodity group i to the wholesale price of commodity group i quoted by foreign suppliers,31 and the level of domestic production. _ Pxi Pusi ui/l-ui - f (Pdi 3 P01 ) Pj) [3] where Pxi is the U.S. export price index of group i to area j. (l960=100) Pu.s.i is the domestic wholesale price index of commodity group i in the United States. (l960=100) P01 is the wholesale price index of commodity group i of foreign suppliers, (l960=100) and, 3OSee "An Econometric Analysis of International Trade, an Interrelated Explanation of Imports and Exports of OECD Countries," by F. G. Adams, H. Eguchi, and F. Meyer-zu-Schlochtern. OECD Economic Studies Series, January, 1969. 31Since tariff reductions received by the United States were extended to all other supplying nations as a result of the Most-Favored-Nation clause, the import prices of the U.S. and foreign suppliers in area j would decline by the same percentage. Thus any relative price shift can be attributed to changes in wholesale prices which are unrelated to duty levels. 57 Pdi is the wholesale price of domestically produced group i commodities in area j. (l960=100) The U.S. price of group i in area j is taken from the following identity: Pxi = Pu.s.i (l + Ti) [4] where Ti is the average nominal ad valorem tariff rate levied on goods within commodity category i by area j. Combining equations [2], [3] and [4] yields: Pu.s.i Pu.s.i xg=rt1 [51 Pdi Pci The dependent variable Xi will be taken as a linear 32 Pu.s.i Pu.s.i combination of the four variables P .______ Jam: ) Pdi Pci and (1 + Ti) j Pu.s.i Pu.s.i . = + _ + ___._.__. Xl do qlPJ + a2 ( Pdi ) a3( Pci ) + a4 (1 + Ti) + e1 [61 where do is a constant for all product classes, and ei is a random disturbance term. The equations will be run on quarterly data for the period 1955-I--1965-IV. With the exception of the EEC, the reductions made by Canada and the United Kingdom were put into effect in 32While non-linear (logarithmic) demand functions estimated by least-squares procedures have the desired property of yielding parameters in the form of elastic- ities, preliminary work suggested the linear form produced a better statistical fit to the data. 58 one stage beginning in 1962. In the EEC case, the concessions granted were in terms of the ultimate Common External Tariff to which the national tariff of the Member States were to move during the transitional period which was to be completed by the end of 1963. It is reasonable to expect that the responsiveness of U.S. exports to changes in the tariff level will increase as the time period under investigation is lengthened. Furthermore, U.S. exports may not respond immediately to once-and-for-all changes in the tariff structure, but rather only after some lag. A lagged response to changes in the relative price structure also seems a reasonable assumption since it may take time for the export sector of the U.S. economy to adjust to the new level of foreign demand. Unfortunately, we have no reason to suspect any particular lag structure which would best describe the responsiveness of U.S. exports to tariff liberalizations or relative price changes. However, a useful technique to deal with the problem of multiple lags has been developed by Shirley Almon.33 The "Almon" technique has the virtue of permitting the data to determine the shape of the weight distribu- tion of the lag structure rather than imposing a 33For a completely detailed account of the math- ematical underpinning and actual procedures of this technique see, Shirley Almon, "The Distributed Lag between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures," Econometrica, Vol. 33, No.1, January, 1965, pp. 178-195. 59 completely pre-determined shape. The idea is that if we can find the "true" weights for a few periods in the time interval, this will be sufficient to define the mathematical function which best describes the distribution of the weights3u for all periods. If, for example, the weight distribution turns out to be a straight line, finding two points on this line is all that is necessary to develop a formula which will give the values for all points on this line. In general, however, this technique is best suited for establishing the values of weights whose configuration is more complicated than that of a straight line. This tech- nique will be employed in our analysis in order to determine the responsiveness of U.S. exports to changes in relative prices and tariff levels over time. In estimating equations for U.S. exports as basically determined by foreign demand, prices in the importer's country, prices in the United States, prices of competitive supply countries, and the level of tariffs, 35 we will use the weighted average of the foreign whole- sale prices listed in column (2) to represent the 3“In this connection, the weights appear in the equation as the best—linear-unbiased-estimates of the coefficients of the lagged independent variable. th 35The weights will be total U.S. exports of the i-— commodity group to area j in year t. 6O competitive supply price in the equations for U.S. exports to the areas listed in column (1). (1) European Economic Community United Kingdom FT? Canada (2) Canada, United Kingdom Canada, European Economic Community United Kingdom, European Economic Community Once the coefficients are determined, implicit tariff elasticities of foreign demand for U.S. exports of category 1 may be calculated by assuming a given percentage change in the tariff level, and calculating the absolute increase in exports resulting from it. The ratio of this change to the mean value of the dependent variable will then represent the tariff elasticity. Mathematically, if X = a + tT and AX = t AT, then a 1 percentage point decline in T would cause an absolute increase in exports of AX = t. 01. Thus, the ratio of AX to X, AX/X, where X is the mean of the dependent variable represents the percentage increase in U.S. exports in response to a 1 percentage 61 point decline in the tariff level. The latter constant will be taken as the tariff elasticity of import demand implied by the equation coefficients. In this connec- tion, to find the total effect of the tariff reduction on export performance over time, we will algebraically sum the coefficients of the lagged tariff variable. This sum is designated by t, above. A similar technique may be used to estimate the papal relative price elas- ticity of the demand for U.S. exports of category 1. In this case however, the algebraic sum of the price coefficients may be used as an indication of the total price multiplier. Both terms, pr and pc, have the U.S. wholesale price index in the numerator. Once the tariff elasticity is determined it is a simple matter, given the actual reduction in the tariff rate, to estimate the percentage increase in U.S. exports which occurred as a result of tariff liberalization. Applying the percentages to the value exported in the base year 1960 will yield the absolute increase in U.S. exports of each commodity group in response to tariff reductions. The sum over all groups will be taken as the effect of the Dillon Round negotiations on all U.S. export trade. Perhaps the major shortcoming of this technique lies in the necessity of implicitly assuming an infinite elasticity of export supply. In other words, our model 62 assumes that any increase in foreign demand resulting from tariff reductions can be supplied at constant costs. The implication of this assumption with regard to the measurement of the total terms of trade effect is discussed in Chapter VII. Exports occupy a relatively small share of total production in the United States, in contrast to many European nations, making the U.S. export supply elasticity much higher than elsewhere. Furthermore, during the early 1960's the U.S. economy was characterized by high levels of unemployment. This excess capacity coupled with high resource mobility suggestS‘Uun:export expansion could be brought about without significant increases in the cost of production. The only direct estimation of supply functions appears in the IMF's world trade model.36 This model includes three equations, one each for the United States, Western Europe, and the rest of the world, relating export prices of the region to an internal price level (except in the case of the rest of the world), the volume of exports and time (presumably to allow for technological change shifting the demand schedule over time). The estimated price elasticities of export supply are: plus 15.0 for the United States, 36R. R. Rhomberg, R. Randall, and L. Boissoneault, "Effects of Income and Price Changes on the U.S. Balance of Payments," IMF Staff Papers, 11:1 (March, 1964) pp. 58-124. 63 plus 2.5 for Western Europe, and plus 1.2 for the rest of the world. If these elasticities are reasonably indicative of the order of magnitude of the supply elasticities involved in international trade, they imply that the tacit assumption of an infinite elasticity of supply (in the case of the United States) used in ordinary least-squares estimation of demand curves from time series data may be warranted. Data A thorough-going revision in United States tariff nomenclature took effect on August 31, 1963, under the Tariff Classification Act. It thus becomes necessary to use two statistical sources from which to obtain data on United States imports. For 1960, data are available from Report No. Ft. 110, U.S. Imports of Merchandise for Consumption, while Ft. 246, U.S. Imports for Consumption and General Imports will be used to obtain 1965 import data. The latter is presented in terms of the classifications contained in the Tariff Schedules of the United States Annotated (TSUSA). Only those classifications unaffected by the nomenclature changes can be directly compared between the years 1960 and 1965. For those classifications which were revised, comparisons will be made by matching commodity descrip- tions and tariff levels existing after the negotiations. 64 The information provided by the commodity description will enable the Schedule A commodities to be uniquely matched to their TSUSA counterparts. The Unites States Department of State reports, Analysis of U.S. Negotia- padaa, Vols. I-IV, contain the relevant information concerning the tariff concessions both granted and received by the United States. Commodity groups will be made comparable by using the Schedule A commodity classifications. In some instances where a commodity appearing in one group in 1960 was re—classified to another in 1965, it will be considered as belonging to the original Schedule A classification. This will be done in order to maintain uniformity as well as make the results comparable with those studies done prior to the revision. A commodity will be eliminated from the study if there is inadequate quantity information or if a suitable substitute is unavailable. With regard to exports, value data are available for the years 1955-1965 in the Department of Commerce publication Report No. Ft. 420, United States Exports of Domestic and Foreigp Merchandise Country of Destination by Subgroup. In 1964, there was a revision of the 5-digit Schedule B numbers to a new Schedule B numbers to which they were assigned. This list will be used when 65 necessary for maintaining consistency within subgroups before and after the conversion. While quantity statistics are called for in the model, constant dollar amounts (l960=100) will be used in order to make cross-product calculations possible. The U.S. domestic wholesale price indices by subgroup which will be used are available for the years 1955-1965 from the U.S. Department of Commerce publication, Statistical Abstract of the United States, while quarterly wholesale price indices of the United Kingdom and Canada may be obtained from various issues of Eda Board of Trade Journal, published by Her Majesty's Stationary Office, and the Bank of Canada's Statistical Summary respectively. An aggreagte index of the wholesale price indices of the EEC will be constructed by aggregating the various country indices, weighting each country series by its share of U.S. exports in year t. References to the sources of these price series and all raw statistical data are presented in the statistical appendix. | If mmfli‘.H-_ n— a- n” ' u 23"? y , vi.._- ' .t A CHAPTER V THE EFFECT OF THE DILLON ROUND ON UNITED STATES IMPORTS Table 7 summarizes the results of this investiga— tion with regard to American imports. The reduced group, (i.e., those commodities which underwent tariff revision) included two hundred and twenty-three commodities amounting to $745.9 million in 1960, or 52.3 per cent of the total value of U.S. import concessions.37 The non-reduced group, or control group, was comprised of an equal number of close substitutes in consumption, valued at $735.2 million in 1960. The two groups were made comparable by selecting the non-reduced group in such a way as to roughly equate it to the reduced group with respect to commodity composition and the average value of imports in the two years under consideration. The latter constraint on our sample was necessary to assure that any differences observed in the behavior of the two groups were due to the tariff changes and not merely reflecting differences in the weights. 37The United States negotiated tariff reductions on industrial imports valued at $1,494 million in 1960. 66 67 o.wm cm ~:.m . mH.mm asopo noosemuucoz m.om cm H:.ou mm.m+ Hz.om 00.: ms.: an.mm azopu omoscmm muosoopm msomcmaamowflz m.o: em ms.sfi- :m.m . asopo emosompucoz m.n: om :H.:I mH.m+ om.:m mm.© om.@ I am.» macho omosomm muosuopm Umpma tom pom mHmOHEoco H.mmw m: ma.mfi ma.HH asogo cmosnmuucoz m.mom m: c~.HI :m.c+ Hm.:m :m.a Hm.mm om.HH asopo omosomm Ammfiowco> new mocficomz .och mposcogm Hmpmz 0cm mamumz H.©ca ma mm.HmI No.0 qsopo boospop|coz m.HHH ma cm.o: ms.H+ wo.fim ac.m mm.o: 05.5 ozooo woosomx mfimpmcfiz cvfihmuozncoz m.cm mm mm.mmu sm.Hm dsopo couscogucoz m.om mm cc.m- ma.o+ ac.am so.m :m.mm mm.am uneto amuseom muozcopi umpma Imm ocm moafipxmh o.mm an rw.m mn.n adopo pmosoopucoz ~.Hm :m :m.c: gc.fl+ um.mm cm.m 0:.wm m~.m dzopo cmozpom Loamm ucm U003 z.mmo mmm ma.n mm.oH azopo Umozvopucoz w.m:m mmm mo.H| mm.o+ 4w.mm om.m nm.om Ho.HH ozone Umosowm moHpHUoEEoo HH< Amcofifiaflzv ooHLQ oofipd pcoo Loo pcoo Loo pcoo Loo pcoo pod uLOQEH upooxm mufipmb moflpd monow omflm oHoEmm zpfipcmza movapm czam> CH mmcmno no ucoo pod mm :fi uLOme ommgo>< mmmpcoopmm :ofiposnom muHLmB mwcmco CH owcmco 'll'l,ll ‘4‘-“ '..II I'A|.II|II'IIIII' .mupoasfi meMpm Umpfics Mo mESHo> 6cm mmOHLQ on» so mcofimmmocoo madam» mo muomwmm chII.~ mqm<9 68 For all commodities, the reduced group experienced a 23.68 per cent reduction in the average tariff rate existing in 1960, which constituted 2.30 per cent of 1960 prices. These results suggest that the average ad valorem rate for the reduced group declined from 9.7 per cent to 7.4 per cent of 1960 prices.38 Between 1960 and 1965, the average foreign export price of the reduced group increased by 11.01 per cent, while that of the non-reduced group increased by 10.69 per cent, a difference of 0.32 percentage points. Thus foreign export prices rose by a total of 0.32 per cent over the five year period, while the import price fell by 1.98 per cent, (i.e., 2.30-0.32). These results suggest that more than 85 per cent of the tariff concessions granted by the United States was passed on to the domestic consumer, while less than 15 per cent accrued to foreign exporters in the form of higher export prices. Our estimates seem to support Kreinin's expectation that a larger share of subsequent tariff o reductions would be passed on to domestic consumers.3’ 38The average nominal ad valorem rate for all manufactured commodities has been estimated to have been 11.6 per cent in 1962. Therefore, it seems that the reduced group was subject to a below average level of protection. See B. Balassa, "Tariff Protection in Industrial Countries: An Evaluation," op.cit. 39M. E. Kreinin, "Effect of Tariff Changes on the Prices and Volume of Imports," American Economic Review, June, 1961, p. 317, Footnote 17. 69 These price changes were accompanied by a 22.81 per— centage point differential between the rates of growth of the two groups. The tariff reduction of 23.68 per cent is in excess of the 20 per cent authority permitted by the 1958 extension of the Trade Agreements Act. One possible explanation of this result lies in the fact that a major portion of United States imports which underwent revision in tariffs during the negotiations were sub- Jected to compound rates of duty, consisting of ad valorem rates coupled with specific duties. When reduced to their ad valorem equivalents, in many cases, effective reductions in duty of more than 20 per cent were realized. Another factor which may account for the size of the overall reduction in the tariff is the authority to reduce tariffs down to 50 per cent ad valorem, or by 2 percentage points. If the duty is above 62.5 per cent, or below 10 per cent ad valorem, this authority constitutes more than a 20 per cent reduction. Since the products comprising the non-reduced group were selected on the basis of their substitutability for commodities of the reduced group, and thus by virtue of experimental design, competitive, it becomes necessary to consider the effect of the tariff concessions 70 upon the non-reduced category. The price of the non- reduced group may have risen by more than 10.69 per cent had they not been affected by the reduced prices of their close substitutes which were the subject of tariff reductions. Thus, our estimate of the 1.98 percentage point differential accruing to the consumer must then be viewed as a minimum. The growth of import volume must also be considered in light of its effect upon the growth of the non—reduced group. The increase in imports of commodities of the non-reduced category may have been retarded by the increased demand for its close substitutes. Our figure, therefore, tends to overstate the effect of tariff concessions on the volume of American imports. With these qualifications in mind, it is possible to obtain an approximate measure of the "nominal tariff elasticity" of import demand and export supply. This concept can best be defined as the response of a change in import volume to a change in prices of manufactures associated with a change in their tariff. No allowance has been made for changes in input prices. In response to a decline in the import price of 1.98 per cent, import volume increased by 22.81 per cent suggesting an elasticity of import demand of -ll.5. Since price changes may be understated while quantity changes may 71 be overstated, our estimates are probably upper-bound elasticities. Kreinin,“O using a cross-sectional approach subject to the same limitations as our method, analyzed data pertaining to the negotiations in 1955 and 1956. The elasticities implicit in his results are -7.1 for all commodities excluding textile between 1954 and 1956 and -9.2 for finished manufactures in the period 1955-1959. Since we allowed a longer period of adjustment than did Kreinin, it is not surprising that our overall elasticity estimate appears to be somewhat larger. Similarly, an increase in the average foreign export price of 0.32 per cent induced an increase in export volume to the United States of 22.81 per cent yielding an export supply elasticity of +7l.3. This figure suggests that, in the long-run, the assumption of an infinite elasticity of export supply fairly approxi- mates existing conditions. For short-run analysis, however, this assumption may be unwarranted. Before any further conclusions can be drawn, the statistical significance of the observed difference between the calculated means of the two groups must be determined. Our "null" hypothesis is that there is no Ibid. 72 statistical difference between the weighted means of the reduced and nonreduced groups. This test was conducted for the average foreign export prices of the two groups as well as for the changes in volume during the period. The results are shown in Table 8.”1 The probability of the observed difference in the means occurring by chance is so large that we must accept the "null" hypothesis and conclude that no significant difference has been demonstrated between the behavior of the tariff-reduced group and that of the non—reduced group. However, although the results pertaining to the overall effect of the tariff conces— sions on the prices and volume of imports are enlight- ening, much information is lost due to the high degree of aggregation. Therefore, we have constructed various commodity groups by combining the individual products into the major Schedule A commodity categories. (Schedule A Nos. 3-9). 0f the six commodity categories studied, Metal and Metal Products (including machinery and vehicles) clearly dominated the total. Inadequate quantity information for the variety of products in the Machinery and Vehicles subgroup made it necessary to include the remaining commodities with items in the Metals and ulSee Appendix A for a detailed description of the test used. ' 11.; ,r' v 73 . ~‘I'Ii 3‘ .,L (15.1", mw.o w:.o m m so.o+ Hs.o om.o Ho.mm mmm mm.o Hm.mm m m m m ml cm Aspcflmpcmouoo.av mocmso an mcflppsooo pompmq Lo owpmq mm mocopommfio em>cmmno co spflaflnmoocm monopomMfiQ mo Logpm chmccmpm mammz on» cmoZumm moocmpoQMHQ Um>pmmno owpmfismpmup z .moflufiUoEEoo HHpomoo mo cosmofimficwfim mo ummBII.m mqm¢e 74 Metal Products category. The few products which were available for analysis, however, accounted for the major portion of the value of commodities in the Machinery and Vehicles subgroup receiving concessions. Concessions were granted on 159 classes of metals and manufactures other than machinery and vehicles involving 1960 imports of $170.0 million, or 12 per '3“ cent of dutiable imports in this commodity group. All Of the concessions were reductions in duty except in , four instances where existing duties covering $809,000 i were bound at existing rates. About 60 per cent ($105.8 million) of total imports of the concession products were in the steel mill products subgroup. Concessions in other subgroups involved imports of $17 .2 million of brass and bronze manufactures, $18.3 million of iron and steel making raw materials, $8.7 mi llion of advanced manufactures of iron and steel, $7 - 2 million of jewelry and plated ware, and miscel- lal’ieous amounted to approximately $12.1 million. By far the largest concessions granted during the. 1960-61 negotiations pertained to machinery and Vehicles, accounting for 48 per cent of total imports or all commodities on which agreement was reached at the Conference. These concessions included more than 1’40 classes of imports in which trade totaled $876.5 m1 llion. Duty reduction on automobiles and parts 75 covered $626.2 million, or 71 per cent of this trade. The remaining concessions affected imports on various types of machinery and apparatus amounting to $250.3 million in 1960. While these concessions were extended to all contracting parties they primarily benefited the European Economic Community which was a principal supplier of these commodities in 1960. Our sample consisted of 45 commodities which underwent downward revisions in their tariff rates and 45 substitutes in consumption not receiving concessions. This sample accounted for more than 51 per cent of the combined total of concessions in both commodity categories. Tariff rates experienced a decline of 24.21 per cent. Since the duty level was already quite low when negoti- ations began,”2 this reduction constituted only a 1.94 per cent decrease in the tariff as a per cent of the foreign price. Prices of the reduced group rose on the average by 11.99 per cent, in contrast to an increase of 11.75 per cent for their immediate substitutes. Thus, tariff reductions were responsible for an increase in the average foreign export price of (11.99-11.75)=0.24 per cent, and consumers benefited from an import price uzThe average ad valorem equivalent duty of our sample was 8 per cent in 1960. This level conforms to the estimates made by Balassa for 2-digit SITC groups in the Metal and Metal Products category (op.cit., Table l). 76 decline of (1.94-0.24)=1.70 per cent. These price changes were accompanied by an import volume increase of (32.81-16.79)=l6.02 per cent. Our results imply an import demand elasticity of —9.4, and an export supply elasticity of +66.7. Of the six categories, chemicals and related products underwent the largest decline in import prices reflecting a low import demand elasticity relative to export supply. 0n the other hand, import prices of non-metallic minerals declined by a modest 0.29 per cent as a result of a highly elastic import demand schedule. As expected, the quantity demanded of most of the commodity groups exhibited a higher degree of responsiveness to price changes than did "total imports." A "T" test was performed on these groups in order to ascertain whether the observed differences between the sample groups for each commodity class were significant. The results are presented in Table 9. The reduced groups of the Wood and Paper, Non- Metallic minerals, and Metal and Metal Products categories each experienced significant differences in their rate of growth from that of their control groups with respect to volume and prices. Chemicals and related products, while undergoing a significant change in price structure demonstrated that the esti- mated increase in the volume of the reduced group of 77 .Ho>oH pcmo god m one pm pcmowpflcmflm >HHm0Hpmempm mum mozam> * Hm.H 0H.H :N.m m0.mH 0m 0m.m 0m.0H msomcmfifimomfiz *H0.m mH.H 00.0 00.0 00 0H.m 0:.HH ma00a§m£0 $00.H *0m.m NH.0 0m.a m: 0m.0 m0.0fi .00000000 H0002 0:0 H0002 *Hm.m *0m.m 05.0 0H.am mH mg.H m0.00 mfimsmcfiz OHHfimpmzucoz 00.0 0H.H Hm.0 mfi.fi0 mm 00.0 am.a0 00000000 ampmamm 0:0 mflfipxme *0m.fi *sw.m 00w0 mzwmfl am 00MH 0aw0m 00000 000 0002 a a a e m @ mocogmmuflo mo mcoHuw>Lomoo pcob wcmoi on» coozpom 0H00H0000-0 omosomcuaaficmp 0:0 00 poppm Upmpcmpm IcmdoocH mo .02 mmocomommflo cm>pmmpo .onpw hpflooEEOO zollmqsogm Umoscmplcoc map pcm mdzouw mcmoE ozp cmozpmn mocmgomaflo po>pmmoo mo mocmOflchme mo pmmBII.m mqm pew zuocficomz wcHUSHocH .mposoopm Hopmz cam mampmz w Ucm w ©.ow mfimpmcflz oHHHmpmzscoz m m.mw mopzpommscmz ocm mpmofim oafluxme m AcoHHHHE av mpLOQEH mUoo ApHUoEEoo CH mmmopocH soapaapomma msopc mpfiooEEoo < masomnom .ccsom COHHHQ map mo mocmsvmmCOo m mm mopOQEH CH mowmmgocfi pohmE wcfiocmfipmaxo mazopw anacoEEOOII.oa mqmtithaker and MageeSO assert that their experimentation ESngggested that supply elasticities in the long-run are 1FEifirrly high. While for many industrial nations the Share of exports to total production may be high, U.S. e‘J'CIDQrts occupy a relatively small share of domestic IDIFCDCiuction, making high elasticities of export supply \ t; uglnternal Tariffs were lowered by 30 per cent during P153 1960-65 period. E3 50H.S. Houthaker and S.P. Magee, "Income and Price JLEisticities in World Trade," Review of Economics and §§liéijzistics, May, 1969, footnote 1. 86 quite likely. Furthermore, the degree of elasticity of foreign demand will vary inversely with the share of imports from the U.S. to total consumption. Since the latter proportion can be expected to be high in the areas studied, a priori we can expect a high import demand elasticity relative to the elasticity of export 1‘ supply. Thus, the tariff reduction would accrue to the ’ aomestic consumer in the form of lower import prices, rather than as higher per unit prices received by the U-S. exporter. _ 0f the five commodity categories studied, machinery and vehicles exports to the U.K. and the IEIEC were the most responsive to tariff changes, while the demand for U.S. textile exports to the United Kingdom exhibited a high degree of insensitivity to tariff reduction (the coefficient was found not to be Significantly different from zero at the 5 per cent level of significance). Similarly, exports of metals and wood products to Canada do not seem to have been effected significantly by the reduction in duty level. United States exports subject to tariff reduction Llrlderwent an average reduction in duty level of 20.6 per cent, constituting a 4.7 per cent decline in the tariff as a per cent of the American export price. These DI‘Zl-cze reductions were followed by a 44.4 per cent 11“Grease in the volume of U.S. exports during 1960-1965. 87 Applying this percentage to the total value of industrial goods receiving concession (i.e., $1,29l.l million) suggests that as a direct result of duty reductions, U.S. exports increased by $573.2 million during the 1960-1965 period. (See Table 12.) SUMMARY The Effect of the Dillon Round on United States Trade The Dillon Round of negotiations effected the unit values and volume of United States trade as shown in Table 13. While a determination of the benefit accruing to tfine U.S. exporter and foreign consumer was not possible, we have determined that foreign export prices rose on the average of 0.32 per cent, while a 1.98 per cent reductiOn in import prices was passed on to the American consumer. United States exports of merchandise amounted to $19.4 billion in 1960. Thus, the increase in exports due to the Dillon Round was 2.9 per cent of total exports. Similarly, merchandise imports in the same year were $15.0 billion indicating an increase of 2.3 per cent of the total as a consequence of tariff negotiations. Therefore, it is estimated that the Dillon Round had a net favorable effect on the U.S. 88 .npgoaxm 000000 0000:: no mESHo> map so wconmmocoo mmapmp mo 0.H00 0.0 0.0 0.H 0.00m H.00 0.00 0.00H 0.00H 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 n.0H chofiaafiev mupoaxm CH mwmmpocH ousaomn< 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.0m 0.00 m.00 0.0 0.00 mptoqu 00 mmmwpocH mprcmopmm HH.01 00.01 0m.010m.01 0H.0| 00.01 H0.H1 00.01 00.01 00.01 0m.a|00.m| H0.01 0m.01 mpHOHummHm 000009 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 mowga uo pcmo pma mm uufipme 0H mcfiaooo 0.00 0.0a 0.00 0H 0.00 00 H0 00 00 0.0a 00 ma H0 00 mufipma CH mcHHomU wwmucmopmm 0.000.H 00 0.0 0.00 000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 000.0 0.00 0.000 0.m 0.00 AmcoHHHHEV 000a CH ovate Hmpoe H0000 coo: .00: 00000 .000: .um: .comfi .Emco 00000 0003 .0002 .pxme .Emco Q3000 mufiooEEoo 00900 000000 000 .0.0 cofiumcfiumoo pomhmm mEBII.mH mqm<9 89 .pxmu. mmm quLSOm 0.mm0+ 0.00m 0.00+ 0.000 0.00+ mcmpe no mon0mm 0m.o+ 00.0- mppoasH mppoaxm AWCOHHHHE av ApcmO .HQQV mflmaB .m.D mESHO> rHO ®EHSHO> C.“ mmcmzv CH mmmeoCH ApCmo Cmav moHCm CmeLom CH memCo Aquo Cmav moHCm .m.: mmpmpm UmpHCD 0C» 00 @0009 CH mmcmno .mCoHpmeome 00:0000 mg» po 000mmp m mm momma 0mflppmzucfi mmpmpm umpflca CH mmwcmnonn.m0 mqm1f the duty.56 AB represents the original tariff to, Wlulle'CD‘is the level existing after negotiations t1. UDlde total contribution of the United States to the <3luange in world’welfare can be represented-by the area IXIBCD. The import price declined by 1.98 per cent, while ‘tlue foreign export price increased by‘O.32 per cent. 56J. E. Meade, The Theory of International Economic Policy, Vol. II, Trade and Welfare, p. 2014. 100 These price changes were brought about by a reduction in the ad valorem rate from 9.7 to 7.4 per cent. The change in welfare is equal to % (9.7 x 7.4) x $68057 = $58.1“ million. In any comparison of the United States tariff levels with those of the European Common Market and of most other countries of the Free World, one factor should be kept in mind: the United States ad valorem duties are based on f.o.b. valuation of the imported goods rather than on a c.i.f. basis. The United States valuation is made on the foreign or export value, whichever is the higher, and excludes such non-dutiable charges as marine insurance, ocean freight and customs fees, before being subject to duty at ad valorem rates. V On the other hand, the major industrial countries value their imports on c.i.f. cost, that is, the valuation includes cost, ocean freight and insurance. Since the inclusion of these costs has the effect of making the valuation higher, the ad valorem duty applied on c.i.f. valuation as opposed to f.o.b. 58 valuation. We will, therefore, consider the nominal rate of duty to which American exports were subjected 57Domestic port value exclusive of duty. 58Committee for Economic Development, "Comparative Tariffs and Trade, the United States and the European Economic Community," Supplementary Paper No. I“, Vol. I, March, 1963, p. XIII. lOl prior to negotiations to be 11 per cent higher to adjust for the difference in valuation procedure. Following the same procedure as for the United States, the contri- bution of the rest of the world to the change in world welfare is equal to % (25.30 + 20.60)$573.2 = $131.55 million. The increase in total world welfare is then $189.69 million. M. E. Kreinin59 estimated the contribution to world welfare by the United States to be $31.5 million as a result of the 1955 negotiations. His result is smaller than ours since the increase in imports as a result of the Dillon Round was over three times that of the 1955 negotiations. This difference apparently more than offset the effects of differences in the average tariff levels during the two periods. In a more recent article M. E. Kreinin and Bela Balassa6O estimated the welfare effects anticipated from the Kennedy Round of negotiations concluded in 1967. These estimates were made under varying assumptions as to the effects of tariff reductions on import and export prices. Variant II estimates reflect welfare changes 59M. E. Kreinin, "Effect of Tariff Changes on the Prices and Volume of Imports," American Economic Review, June, 1961, Vol. II, p. 321. 60M. E. Kreinin and B. Balassa, "Trade Liberaliza- tion Under the 'Kennedy Round': The Static Effects," The Review of Economics and Statistics, May, 1967, Vol. XLIX, pp. 125-137. 102 which do not entail changes in the terms of trade, while Variant I estimates take into account the pos- sibility of rising export prices. For the United States the total gain in welfare is estimated to be $56 million under Variant I assumptions and $1A9 million under Variant II. For all industrial nations, these gains are $251 million and $326 million, respectively. One would expect larger gains from the Kennedy Round in light of the large across—the—board reductions (50 per cent in most cases), as opposed to only an average reduction of 23 per cent negotiatied at the 1960-61 Conference. The Terms of Trade The static argument in favor of tariffs at the national level is that under the appropriate circumstances a tariff will enable the country to obtain its imports cheaper. A country's terms of trade are improved, and its share in the gain from trade therefore increased, if import prices are lowered relative to its export prices. In the partial-equilibrium case, Figure A shows the effect of a tariff in widening the spread between prices in the exporting and importing countries. 103 Figure A Importer E porter S P is the price with trade, before the imposition of a tariff, assuming no transportation costs. P1 is the jprice in the importing country, while P2 is the price :in the exporting country after the tariff is imposed. iIn this case, where the elasticities of demand and supply are roughly the same in both countries, the ‘tariff will partly raise the price in the importing country and partly lower the price in the exporting' Ination. If the price in the exporting country is lowered eat all, however, the country imposing the tariff gets 'the product cheaper. The extent to WhiCh a tariff can fimprove the terms of trade depends upon existing eslasticity conditions. In the extreme case where the 104 p>roduction of a commodity takes place at constant costs zabroad and increasing costs in the home country, the ianosition of a tariff will not lower the price :received by the exporters. On the other hand, if the demand for the product is relatively elastic when compared to the export supply curve, the effect on the foreign export price of a tariff may be quite severe. This means that the gain realized by the country imposing the tariff is at the expense of other countries; that is, the distribution of world income is altered in favor of the tariff—levying country. When tariffs are lowered unilaterally the opposite effect occurs. In the absence of perfectly elastic supply curves, a reduction in the level of protection ‘will be associated with a deterioration in the terms of trade of that nation vis a vis the rest of the world. 'The extent of this deterioration depends, for the most ‘part, on the underlying elasticities of demand and supply in the country, or countries, receiving the concessions. When multilateral tariff negotiations take place, the effect upon a country's terms of trade will depend Lumnu (a) the amount of protection it gives up in the :form of concessions to other countries; (b) how ssuccessful it is in inducing other countries to lower tzheir tariff barriers, and (c) the existing elasticities 105 c>f import demand and export supply. We will be concerned vvith the net barter terms of trade, more commonly called izhe commodity terms of trade, Tc’ It affords a measure c>f how much imports a country will receive for its exports. IIt is the ratio of the price received for its exports to ‘the price paid for imported goods. If OPX and OPm61 are the prices existing in the base period for exports and imports, respectively, and lPx and le are the export and import prices in period 1, the terms of trade can be expressed as 1Px/0Px T = —————-— [l] C P P l m/o m It therefore measures the trend over time in the amount of foreign goods received in exchange for one physical unit of export goods. Mathematically, we can find the percentage change in the terms of trade by differentiating the function 'Tc = f(Px,Pm), where TC is the commodity terms of trade, and Px and Pm are the prices of United States exports and imports, respectively. If TC = Px/Pm’ then dTC dP dePm dPX Tchm , which equals ———-- P P 2 Pm Pm m m , therefore, 61The relevant price for imports is the foreign jprice excluding tariffs. ,—‘ 106 dTC dPX de —-——-—-——--———. [2] T P P In words, the percentage change in the terms of trade of the United States is equal to the difference between the percentage change in the price received for its exports and the percentage change in the price paid for its imports. The price paid for imported goods excluding tariffs can also be viewed as being the price received by foreign exporters for their exportables. Thus, the percentage change in terms of trade can be expressed as __.=__.. , [3] where le is the average export price received by foreign exporters. Our results suggest that as a direct consequence of the Dillon Round the United States terms of trade deteri- orated by a modest 0.32 per cent. This estimate must be considered as setting an upper limit to the loss in the U.S. terms of trade since we have assumed no change in the prices received by U.S. exporters. The relatively insignificant change in the terms of trade reflects in part our assumptions of an 107 infinitely elastic export supply curve for the United States. Exports occupy a very small share of total production in most American industries, which has the effect of making the U.S. export supply curve more elastic than for countries which are heavily engaged in production for export. Secondly, the high level of mobility of resources in the United States can also explain why an expansion in production can take place without a significant increase in costs. The terms of trade of a nation must obviously take account of all the prices of all commodities which enter into international trade. We have only focused upon the industrial sector and as such have measured only a part of the whole effect of the negotiations on the overall terms of trade. It would, therefore, be more correct to say that our estimate shows the effect of the changes in the relative prices of industrial products upon the terms of trade. When the prices of agricultural products are taken into consideration, it is quite possible for changes in agricultural prices to offset any loss sustained as a result of negotiations on industrial goods. On balance, it appears that the Dillon Round had a neutral effect on the terms of trade of the United States. 108 The Employment Effect We have already seen that the reduction of tariff barriers causes a reallocation of productive resources to more efficient uses. As tariffs are reduced multi- laterally, there will be a shift in employment away from import-competing industries towards those industries producing for export. Our analysis now turns to the relationship between the expansion of foreign trade and its impact upon domestic employment. In two related studies, the Bureau of Labor Statistics investigated the relationship between exports and imports and domestic employment.62 In Employment in Relation to U.S. Imports, all 1960 imports ($17.6 billion c.i.f.) were divided into two categories: supporting imports and competitive imports. Of the competitive imports ($6.8 billion), all manufactured imports (divisions 19-39) account for a major portion, specifically ($6.3 billion). For our purposes only the estimate pertaining to the second category is relevant. It shows the number of workers that would have been required to produce 62U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Domestic Employment Attributable to U.S. Exports, 1960 and Employment in Relation to U.S. Imports, 1960, Washington, 1962 (mimeographed). See also U.S. Department of Labor, BLS, The Relationship Between Imports and Employment (An analysis of 27 import com- pleting industries, and 2 industry case studies, Washington, April, 1962 (mimeographed)). 109 these imports in the United States. It consists of: (a) direct employment, (b) indirect employment, and (c) employment required to replace plant and equipment. The BLS estimated that to produce all the competitive imports would require 916.2 thousand workers both directly and indirectly. At the same time 73.7 thousand would be necessary to replace plant and equipment, and 83 thousand workers would be necessary to handle transportation and distribution to the next stage of production. The total is 1,072.9 thousand 1,072,900 $6,808.6 workers yielding an arithmetic average of ( = 157.6 workers per million dollars worth of com- petitive imports. 0n the other hand, the BLS study relating to domestic employment and exports, shows that 3,081,700 workers were required to produce $22,055.3 million worth of exports. These figures suggest an average of 138.7 workers per $1 million of exports. The above data refer to all trade, including trade in agricultural products and thus cannot be directly applied to the estimation of the effect of the Dillon Round on employment. The two studies present the direct and indirect effect on each industry, but they do not show the effect on employment due to output changes within each industry. Thus even though 110 for the direct impact the two figures are identical, the indirect effect in each industry is not given. M. E. Kreinin,63 in a study of the effects of an Atlantic Free Trade Association was able to overcome this deficiency in the data. For each of some 200 industries, a 1960 employment matrix which shows the number of jobs required directly and indirectly, to produce $1 million of output in 1960, was used to ascertain the indirect requirements of each of the six major sectors (agriculture, mining, manufacturing, transport, trade, and all others). By the use of arithmetic averages, the BLS employment estimates were aggregated into two-digit SIC divisions. In Appendix IV-A for each two-digit SIC division, he presents the job requirements per $1 million of final demand in 1960. Since our results pertain to the major Schedule A commodity groups, it was necessary to aggregate his results into these major classifications. Table 14 presents estimates of the employment changes in each major commodity group (last two columns), obtained by applying the BLS coefficients (first column) to the estimated changes in trade as a consequence of the Dillon Round. 63M. E. Kreinin, Alternative Commercial Policies-q Their Effect on the American Economy, MSU International Business and Economic Studies, Institute for International Business and Economic Development Studies, Division of Research, 1967. 111 .masopw 03» on» mo mwmmo>m oapmenufipm ocu wcfixmp an venom mm: mpcmEonfizwmp ooh map mo mmeHpmm cm mposoonm Hmumz ocm Hmpmz npfi3 pocHoEoo who: moaoaco> new mamcfinomz wppooEfi pom oocfim * mm.osm.omH wm.mom.fia om.msm oo.o:m Hmpoe 0:.mflm mm.mmm.a NH.N mm.sfl m:.moa mposconm msoocmaamomfiz mfi.mmfi.m mm.mfi om.msfi aposoopm Hmpmz new Hmpmz :m.szm.mm *mz.NSH *:~.omm :s.:om.mm sm.mmm ww.mmm mmHOHnm> w apocfinomz mfi.aom.: mo.mm mm.sw mamtmcfiz Ofiafimpmzucoz am.mmm.flm so.m:m.m ma.:ma mm.Hm mo.HHH mHmOHEmco mm.afim.fi mm.amo.sa Ho.m :s.mm mm.mmm moussomm Inca: a wmfifiuxme m:.HmH.m as.ma:.m m©.om mm.mH m:.mmm mposeonm momma w @003 mpsoqu musoaeH wppoaxm *wuLOQEH ocmEoo Hmcfim mo AmQOhV AmcoHHHHE%V COHHHHE Ha poo adopo mufiooEEoo pcoezoaaem CH mowcwzo mompe CH mmwcmzo mpcmEmgfizvmm now Amnow ommfiv Amazonw < mazomnomv oesopomcoo mmfipme Hmlomma ozp mo muommmm pcoemoaaemul.aa mqm00 1,066.0 2,175.5 1,1 3.7 2,330.7 25.0 20.0 3270600 200.6 1,272.7 :06 6 681.0 15.0 12.0 3286000 138.6 026.2 160 3 080.9 12.5 .10.0 3275000 1,966.9 1,375 1 1 013.9 929.0 8.5 6.5 3352130 29.8 5.7 107 1 11.5 30.0 27.5 3250700 663.1 902.3 3,702.0 0,083.6 35.0 28.0 3291000 775.0 206.0 0,335.1 270.6 8.5 6.0 3291500 1,331.3 866.1 5,060.2 3,007.2 33.6 27.6 3291600 375.6 ,60.8 0,767.7 003.0 23.0 18.0 3535050 2,939.1 5,090.8 2,220.6 3,288.0 6.0 0.0 3535000 2.0 3.0 7.2 0.6 1.2 1.0 3373000 887.2 1,818.1 137.1 335.2 19.2 16.7 3661000 30.: 611.7 37.6 570.0 25.5 20.0 3615900 613.0 ,181.0 181.2 298.9 28.2 20.7 3705010 13.8 152.0 3.2 68.3 21.0 17.0 3705390 53.0 13.3 75.1 0.2 21.0 17.0 3706290 1 7.: 131.7 01.6 10.9 25.5 20.0 3727000 21r.7 230.8 38.6 0a.8 21.0 17.0 3729000 31.9 8.9 1.9 0.9 21.0 17.0 3737000 13.0 30.0 11.0 36.8 30.0 20.0 3737200 3.5 37.9 13.7 06.8 30.0 20.0 3703100 6.7 7,093.9 23.0 5,017.2 50.0 00.0 3703000 15.7 32.7 8.5 56.0 25.0 20.0 3800090 1,078.0 1,387.0 601.5 901.0 50.0 00.0 3880000 139.8 261.5 32.6 77.8 31.5 26.5 3902550 1,030.3 1,088.3 :23,725.0 182,108.2 6.0 0.0 3912100 1,278.3 1,385.6 300.1 339.1 18.8 15.1 3912700 388.8 551.0 393.2 303.1 15.0 12.0 3913100 860.8 215.1 132.6 28.6 13.5 10.6 3925000 10.5 03.0 2.1 3.5 03.1 30.7 3925000 000.2 153.6 57.2 20.5 50.8 00.6 3166300 16.7 5.3 78.3 26.8 50.0 00.0 3750310 369.1 505.3 22.0 20.1 30.0 20.0 3850510 77.3 151.7 15.7 52.3 30.0 20.0 3295000 2.1 0.7 0.0 0.2 05.0 36.0 3750390 1.1 1.3 0.2 0.1 38.0 30.0 3168100 1,32 .6 1,366.9 153.3 110.3 35.0 28.0 3851000 250.8 625.0 1,522.8 2,161.2 28.7 23.1 3690000 193.0 3,315.2 05.6 283.9 10.0 8.0 3698700 36.6 382.9 02.9 397.3 10.0 8.0 max 1‘7 r 1330 TABLE B.3.-—Hun-metulllc mineral? (redu*e1 vrrun). 271111e TV1F11‘Y Schedule A 30. (thoaauud; of dallgrr) Oguntitv (Der cent of fareign price) ;0 1:65 1960 1965 1960 1965 \~J ‘ \ 5390050 671.1 317.0 ,179.0 3,537.0 5.0 3.0 R. .J ‘0570 9.1 576.3 10.3 2,537.2 30.0 20.0 W (.0) L1“ 5110300 f'9.7 977.3 1T1,“'fi.i h 2.1 13.9 11.1 \J) a: LA) *4 1,) C.) I 11 _11 l ‘1 7; J A) i 41-,0 (‘1 I]. 7',l-j‘;4-l: 110:) 800 ‘“”“‘O3 1‘” fl 1'7-3 Y."“-“ ;,w'3.“ 21.3 17.5 “33??“3 . ’1.” 1,7*7.~ 11“.? 31.9 0.0 3.1 “ ”‘73 ' - 1‘.* -.~ :1. 21.0 17.0 77" 1“ 7’- 07 '.7 1.3 ,7: . ‘".1 12.5 0.1. j730€00 36.6 19. V J r 1 L N \J )_: “q 11‘ Ch NJ 5‘ U1 \n 5260270 370.1 239.3 ‘ J7 ,262.5 3,231.0 7.1 5.7 5109300 519.0 730.? 133.9 3 166.2 1.6 0.] 5110060 9.1 5.7 L: 0 J} 2’ o O\ 0.9 1.3 \ 5951000 78,036.9 171,827.9 301.9 1,258.7 10.0 8.0 135 TABLE B.U.--Metals and metal products (ro1uced grown). WALK? T112”): ff Schedule A No. (thousands of da111r0) Quantity (per cent of foreign price) 1350 1968 1361 1965 1960 1965 6301500 2,172.3 7, 15.“ 111.5 216.0 U.u 2. 600320 3,ian.8 3%,.7“.3 $6.9 787.5 1. 0. 0212100 123.0 373.0 930.2 1,769.9 Q. 6. 6210080 21.6 126.: 29.2 67.3 19. 15. 6215200 332.3 ?C0.fi ‘,17E.6 3,670.6 12. 10. 6219100 5,637.6 11,331 3 “2,171.9 66,879.u 10. 8 6250360 “1.5 11 C 106.1 33.9 12. 10 6250500 15.3 “7.6 13.6 28.2 17 15 6210600 63.0 02.0 3.1 9.7 12 10 6230610 20.9 1.3 2.0 0.1 12 10 6250655 23.0 23.1 1.; 1.6 12 10 6087200 932. 296.: 16,031.] 6,037.2 10 8. 6081300 300. 2,?42.1 16,~12 3 72,696.? 3 6111800 107. 1,6$2 1 ‘,“ 7 ? 3?,231 7 10 6110500 3,156 1,9f2 T :,1~ 3 r’,77" ~ 6030100 257. 2a,'1« 7 n, 1 0 na9,011 6 6036300 9. 51 ” ”27 2 6113500 6150500 6113200 2, 6113u00 6092600 6092700 6112u00 I) «1 H fix}: 0 O 0001 ‘91 x11 D O l I O I I I H 1“.)‘wa—‘foio\ r—w—u—a zoom 10 omwmmwp H... mwmooowcccmomm U JW KO .“pm‘ 3 ~ 3 ~3\ U C U C . 0 '30 mo (“fp \AJ W U H ‘3\ uk) I £411-71 'QLUKD OM» (Duo Q ‘0 L u: m u as L—1 r: .0 r: .3. 7V“,- 0 no ' up .2 CUP—“UP f—‘ O V )0 *1 \.U FT 0 o o a . I a o n o I o - Fl) \0 Pd \0 «J KL.) LU ,U \) LO \1 \f) KJJ w H 1.x 65uu31o 299. 6158700 36. 6790970 1,386. 7900500 513,659. H \3 HP CW 0 O f—J I“) 2,881. 7M0,026. R) V L.‘ K) J r\) M WOOOOOHWNMNWOHOOOOOONHOOOOOOOWNWOOOOOOOU’IOJ:'\00\£: UTUWU'IWKI'IUWNCDON JDWOKJONOUWOOQWO ~3U'1CDOOOOH 1:0 EOWUW‘JWU‘IUWWUTI‘UFUO 6119600 3’ 3' 1 7‘ .0 65.1: I; 6,013 6200930 7 3. 1 1"F.P 1 197.1 2,803 19 12 6190000 3:7. :‘r 7 :51.7 162 10 8 6790350 2u.6 16 6 31.1 80 20 16 6120000 3.8 0.2 127.1 25 87 50 6120020 0.2 0 6 5.3 13 75 50 6120030 31.1 37.8 323.7 019 88 50 6118200 329.0 391.3 789.9 570 35. 18 6118600 21.3 0.9 309.0 3.0 50 no 6150310 119.6 M1.3 05 9 10.3 5 3 62007u0 128.u 232.2 121.1 291.3 23 20 6200790 76.7 328.2 91.9 93.u 20 17. 6200780 25.2 105.9 0.7 2 .3 2M 19 6200790 2.6 5.7 0.0 0.2 17 1a. 6200800 151.u 51.0 12.0 16.1 22. 18 6790500 u67.9 821.0 557.7 799.9 12. 10 65uu300 18.u 219.0 0.8 98.3 12 10 1 1 1 0.2 .5 7 7 6 .9 8 0 6 .3 1 3 u 1: 1: x:- O\ UWb—J CI) 136 TABLE B.5.—-Chemicals and related products (reduced group). Value Tariff Schedule A No. (thousands of dollars) Quantity (per cent of Foreign price) 1960 1965 1960 1965 1960 1965 8231230 9,362.2 9,012.6 20,200.9 12,125.1 26.8 21.9 1250780 1,669.3 999.1 1,965.5 670.8 20.0 16.0 82115900 130.7 165.11 329.6 582.5 10.5 8.5 8297500 282.7 17 .3 11,567.3 6,010.1 10.5 9.5 8312900 99.3 133.9 6,071.8 7,198.9 10.5 8.5 8380110 8.9 10.7 307.5 311.9 12.6 10.0 8380170 593.9 765.3 6,170.3 6,699.9 10.5 8.5 8380210 99.5 219.6 925.5 279.8 27.3 21.8 8380937 285.3 305.0 835.6 1,862.8 39.1 31.0 8310200 109.9 82.9 2,279.2 1,888.9 6.0 5.0 8380300 57.6 169.9 1,959.2 9,501.5 8.5 6.5 8380982 265.0 188.9 1.7 39.7 12.5 10.0 8050100 70.0 93 0 89.0 22.1 50.1 90.1 2220970 1,985.9 399.2 651.3 555.5 5.0 3.0 2220030 81.6 303.1 299.9 609.7 9.8 3.3 2395000 1,389.1 2,681.7 17,990.6 30,059.9 6.0 9.0 2395800 229.7 55.2 6,395.1 1,519.9 7.5 5.5 0097000 1,071.5 657.5 3,969.7 2,099.7 16.5 13.2 9850900 70.0 170.3 72.9 153.7 7.5 5.5 8050200 10,523.0 3,723.9 3,593.2 1,065.9 110.0 32.0 8070830 128.5 670.8 9.0 96.5 21.0 17.0 8070900 11,758.1 1,509.7 2,995.9 969.7 26.0 21.0 8261000 1,520.2 1,010.6 1,959.2 996.9 3.8 1.9 2278000 790.5 1,195 9 59.9 82.2 10.0 8.0 2290360 27.3 199.2 20.9 88.8 6.3 9.0 2290910 706.6 1 289 7 55.5 177.7 5.0 3.0 8722350 139.3 17“ ; 20.6 ,1.5 20.0 16.0 2200990 2,095.6 1,562.11 2,15 .1 6.3 11.0 2206000 2,863.5 ' 897.1 111.5 629.2 157.0 125.9 8722000 18.5 19..1 0.5 1.1 10.8 8.0 8722150 67.8 103.0 3? 2 68.6 95.0 36.0 8725700 162.9 30.8 35.3 19.9 18.8 15.0 8731100 327.8 3129 31.0.6 92.3 22.3 17.8 8931100 952.9 559.9 121.9 273.3 11.5 9.5 890.2200 19.2 29.9 239.7 5112.9 21.0 17.0 8920270 380.8 88.0 86.9 23.2 11.0 9.0 8931900 229.9 230.9 588.7 1,082.1 10.5 8.5 8920130 192.1 716.9 603.3 2,986.9 12.5 10.0 8325000 136.7 193 6 1,331.9 1,993.3 5.0 2.0 8330900 202.9 905.3 671.9 1,799.6 9.7 7.9 8712500 623.8 1,639.1 899.6 2,52 .9 8.5 6.5 8336000 61.9 292.6 2.7 11.1 5.7 2.2 8390000 107.9 190.6 975.9 1,978.1 6.7 5.0 8391000 0.1 1.9 1.0 22.0 56.3 95.0 8350120 17.3 27.0 210.0 309.0 11.1 8.9 8350390 36.3 22 .3 862.7 3,893.1 7.5 6.0 8380620 5.9 93.2 39.9 359.2 36.6 30.0 8380872 38.7 15.5 9.1 11.0 21.0 17.0 8380570 1.0 2 2.0 2.9 505.7 93.0 39.2 8130870 62.5 228.9 29.6 119.2 15.0 12.0 8380915 7.8 39.7 29.9 183.9 35.0 28.0 8020200 3,325.1 2,992.8 2,925.9 2 995.3 28.5 22.8 8090150 19.9 51.2 7.0 183.2 22.9 18.3 8090760 922.5 789.7 519.1 1,593.0 25.3 20.2 8380350 82.9 30.1 209.6 78.0 6.3 3.8 8090755 969.1 19.5 3,863.9 123.6 97.5 38.0 1337 TABLE B.6.--Miscellaneous (Reduced Group). Value Tariff Schedule A. No. (thousands of dollars) Quantity (per cent of foreign price) 1960 1965 1960 1965 1960 1965 9160560 291.9 198.2 17,952.9 7,582.5 50.0 32.0 9160580 206.8 165.5 11,299.1 6,237.1 50.0 32.0 9970120 925.5 733.3 17.7 33-7 35.5 28.5 9970960 502.6 639.1 11.9 16.0 18.7 15.0 9970982 5,810 1 6,730.0 88.9 91 9 20.0 16.0 9u70985 1,229.9 9,615.6 15.7 91.9 20.0 16.0 9970590 317.9 977.5 19.1 15.3 15.7 12.7 9970550 25.9 27.3 1.7 17.8 99.2 39.9 9970560 95.6 33 0 8.1 5.9 31.9 25.2 9970570 12.8 99.1 0.7 6.3 u1.7 33.3 9970020 839.2 9,018 9 72 3 281.6 91.1 32.9 9590220 29.5 29.0 0.8 0.8 39.2 31.9 9590260 110.1 55.6 0.9 1.0 18.2 15.5 9730090 997 8 165 6 350.1 291.6 22.5 18.0 )730800 529.9 2,1 .7 69.1 3,9‘).9 25.0 20.0 9910860 838.9 1,318.2 35.3 637.1 25.0 20.0 9850500 73.0 “2“ 2 7.1 212.8 39.0 27.0 9260200 79.6 89.3 7.9 7.5 19.0 15.2 9260750 1,830 8 :,567.6 99.5 18.1 20.0 17.0 9212050 696 8 1,09“ 8 38.5 96.7 20.6 16.5 9262200 3,719 3 3,836.8 9,699.2 5,291.9 12.5 10.0 9780270 929.9 695.7 190.1 177.8 0.9 0.3 9780280 8.3 15.3 19.5 35.9 11.6 9.3 9780290 37.1 273.1 21.3 192 20.0 16.0 9001000 3,751.3 3,790 2 189.2 33.9 15.0 12.0 9025600 1,896.5 2,170 9 29,771.8 22,232.3 11.1 8.9 9800010 6.8 39.9 1.9 2. 11.3 9.0 9800200 28.9 233.2 139.1 178.7 93.3 39.7 9800790 28.1 36.9 55.7 59.9 12.5 10.0 9820110 92.1 71.9 7.6 3.5 25.0 20.0 TABLE B.7.-—Hood and paper: 1Q38 brintod matter (nan-roducod grown). 14729910 11726270 31.9 1,927.8 108. .131101101 0 A ‘12 ( 13u711‘f1571 ri“=1‘ 1' 011ur1ti_t37 “760 1361 1960 196 u030030 .1 5: 2 618.0 780.9 1219723 4,370.1 11,300 7 113,53U.7 628,082.5 U23103F 4,191.0 3,377 6 7,937.u 8.813.6 u710130 3: : 1,351 3 5,273.7 6,325.0 u7u0270 _5.6 62.1 172.8 52 .3 u728310 P , 3-9 31-9 1'9 u729810 7“ .7 035.“ 4,557 3 5,785.6 M739930 E 1 10 u 110.5 31.2 “717900 237 752,? 3,811.1 7,855-u 9521700 2.1 5.5 1.5 2.2 u709u60 6? 1 0 8 167.5 2.3 5530510 .5 25.5 0.3 1.9 M72582) *1. "2 39.9 33.9 #723720 1 7.2 139.0 012.7 805.9 M720950 61.8 0.8 155.2 2 .O u775000 673.1 132 2 8 550 6 1,860.8 u7u0192 1, g 2 135 1 27,173 2 2,u95 9 u799590 73.8 2 1 6u.6 1.2 u303000 1,937.3 1,229.3 2 ,208.8 1u,103 u u303100 1.5 0.6 3.5 1.7 u716020 2,682.u 1,99u.0 35,183 6 25,652 9 u726290 7,135.9 1,601.7 6,136.9 1,382 2 Schedule A (LhOUfl “11111;? 139 and n1un1fncture: (11011-110-101:e:l dollars) nrnah). Quantity 3639300 3639500 3166690 3750900 3855900 3296000 3750b00 3855100 3168500 3160800 3696280 3698800 19v 1965 1960 1965 3709300 25.;' 9.6 5.2 1.5 3070010 101.1 375.7 570.9 591.3 3081350 37.3 15.u 27.5 31.1 3181360 1.8 5 7 3.1 2.3 3250600 33.1 6 5 25.7 u.5 3221150 10.8 2 7 00.2 38.u 322M000 711.9 101 5 068.9 u3.9 3086100 211.9 Ml .u 323.0 672.7 3909000 90.3 17H.9 0.6 8.2 3u03000 2,986.9 3,178.0 9.5 23.9 3291500 9,115.1 3,u17.9 5n.6 22.6 3u09700 A36 0 ”11.0 2.6 1.1 3280000 251.9 09.8 1,732.5 900.u 3270700 17.9 0.8 32.0 22.3 3078020 3fii.8 119.0 171.9 76.u 3283?OO 3?%.S 959.3 ““5.“ 3U2.3 3352110 140.1 281.: 837.1 1,912.2 3230270 90L.8 U92.8 579.1 5n6.9 315u100 90: 3 061.3 062.3 1,051.1 319N100 1,910.5 288.9 1,529.0 16u.1 37u3900 1,988.9 2,093.5 2 100.2 5,017.2 3530050 35.6 1.8 28.6 1.6 3538900 ..9 3.8 0.6 2.9 3011000 3,88 .7 1, 05.6 8.916.3 3,08u.u 3670010 931.5 39.8 1,832.0 no.9 3615650 97.0 91.2 58.8 26.6 3706010 3,06‘.0 1,956.1 M86.0 39u.1 3801100 505.1 1,032 9 961.9 1,276.7 3021000 509.5 218 3 365.7 292.6 3622000 00.1 3 1 26.9 27.9 3830100 3:9.0 18 5 108.5 101.6 3635100 2,676.0 2,70 1 U20.1 u03.1 36u1150 615.8 9 190.1 1.8 3160920 1,095. 15 u 12,207.9 1,786.8 3160800 3,595. 2,38 1 32,205.3 1,101.9 3800100 95 33 3 5u,5 232.7 3830200 1,369. 1,76 6 250.9 28u.7 3900u00 636 53 9 78,988.0 52,BU2.7 3913000 59 1,79 6 1,309.1 3,023.9 3912600 59 U9 3 1,133.7 6M3.6 3913u00 3 15 5 139 0 111.7 .u 8 .2 9 1 .0 .u .1 .0 .5 2 .2 .0 u .1 3 l .3 6 .0 5 9 u 5 3 u o 9 5 6 7 .1 u 0 .1 7 |._1 i—J UWO\ DUN] «JP 3 CD OR) 1,397. 1:- \JT H \IWl—J‘JTCDONCDKQO tor—“mml—‘KOLDKOF—‘F—JCNH‘Ob’WfU‘xOy—J‘xQ H two f—‘CDNWMOWMCDO O‘xru DO—\)\1\O’\u T‘QKLDLub—J 1:- C‘CDP—‘W H v H (IDLU f‘x.) {— r\) v 0 KO \2 116. 15. u,831. 767. 1110 leuo .wfijule 11 N1. {11100301u1‘.¢f 1L>llxr l Cfififlitity 1"1 17:1 1‘") 1065 5300590 050.7 3,7a3.7 797.0 16,766.5 5120150 34.5 32.1 1.6 1.u 5063100 11.? +9.7 12,561.u 16,72u.3 5u57300 13 .5 348.7 2,225.7 7,678.0 5301090 13,0fl7.6 13,561.? 393.0 . QUE.“ 5);;3‘ [‘1 ‘.‘j H '1 u6gl’] 8606 5561110 1.C 11.9 ”.2 330.9 5712200 5‘1." 73:.9 31,1“3-3 30.835-0 ‘J’l \1 W C) ” J '3 Q J 1;) H 3 kg) \J I.) \J CO R) ‘4 CO O'\ O\ \0 5730500 7 1.9 51:.7 .,nwF.2 12, / / A “N 330190; 95“.? 137.“ 7,1 :.1 2,913.3 5109500 379.3 1,365.1 98.6 101.2 51100%O 779.0 39.7 35.3 1.0 5950000 88,060.0 96.056.8 1:355”3 1’900'9 1741 \ —.J p- >4 J \_/ .5.) C 1..) -v ._) .—~o \ p—Ao # < “70371 . 63007?3 0. 6300770 6200730 6200760 6790390 éSUUSOD 6311100 75,111.« 111,181.” 9,731.3 12,701.6 ‘ ' I ".‘_.i I-‘- 7 (I. my m 1 1.2-0 6013??) -.},f ‘47.? 1")".I’ 1’7’iil'j.3 370.11.379.11 'S(‘ 12‘7" "“a ‘ P. o Unof' 5109 9117‘» 1 1) 44 W 1, . 19','/}’:J).3 5,??ri05 6219111 C,r‘ .: : :.~ 96,137.8 7,092.3 637,3)21/3’0 \ 7. | 11139,. 1 1717.0 395.5 6217910 1,v» .4 1, ‘.0 1,8 1.8 2,020.8 CH'“’7‘ .3 . 3.1 0.1 '7.'-' ‘r’ 3 v I :1 l. o ;' T‘ 0 )1 36 o 9 rl»5b 3 ".7 .“ 37.7 25.7 6086330 1,01‘.1 1,107.1 1,705.3 u,377.9 [73:7103 ‘ "a ‘ 1,1.‘7107’ 1r,);)y:i).8 39,701.08 “111803 .‘ 71.‘ 35U.9 192.“ {11‘03'Mj H, . ' 3 €1,9"3 3 T),96f3 9 J;‘_I__/L, O u --. ,c , ._ 1x. ,0— 6036210 H.,~x .— 7,1 ‘. 7f1,196.6 767,709.7 6036100 “’7.~ *,2'~.r 7,539.8 ”5,230.9 6113003 1 .' “7.) £“1.3 377.2 6151550 1.1 2.6 13.9 5.0 6111191 1: .2 £3. 1,136.6 u65.1 (1:11—77 , ‘Ar’o‘j .‘,:I1’--'" 0” 1r ,13'3'57‘06 7,387.1 (1)910.) la- 7).); a!"l .7 717,93'3-3 “2,79902 6002709 ‘ 8.1 ',1“«.8 1,916.7 1 ,6uo.8 6112810 I. 8.1 12.1 10.8 6112900 : .' ~2.1 599.1 181.5 6303580 f7.7 ‘i.: 77.5 U3?.S 6153193 417.7 133.5 11,519.? 1“ 973.3 6710330 639.0 8‘7.1 939.9 1,221.1 / .. ,- 1|, ,. ,3, .r '1 >4 . ;:.1 » L)l~?k_l\le‘3 J\.—) i“ ‘01 1,317.5 3,073.5 x E -‘ w~_ ~ ,’—~ / 6139753 .6“.1 . i7.r gfh. 090.3 61?7363 773.? 675.1 556. 569.5 ’ ‘ . I :1" K (’1 0118977 3’71”.” “,‘Jfi.5 0,904. 8,557. 611897? 97.3 73.3 112. 8 . 5150751 35.3 5U.7 5“. 5 . 7 111.7 11. H R) GDOKOI'UU‘IIvl—JOChf—‘Emwk NJ ' t C\ O\ I L)‘3\kD .5 }—’\J7\_nQi—JO\‘OP—J£:I\F—JF—' ‘2.” C D "J1 CD O\ J‘\ C) \x} fi—J kA.) ‘4 “ 0\ G\ N ("I ’ ~.) 6;.) O\ C‘KOODkUUTuDWOI—JOQDNF‘JMONI O\\.OC)J:‘OT\)QF—‘O\LTC 1 3 65uu510 3 . ,. 3 . 3 . 6958050 9,65 .9 12,198. 09,76 . 29,65 . 6790960 32 .8 1,927. 53 . 2,u3 . 7900700 ,60,66 .8 966,003. 2 . . 1142 'TABLE 13211.--Chendmx110 :umj relrmxyd nrwmiucts (vaM—rwniucecitirouo). 17“] . J '1. U‘.‘ Schedule A No. (thousands of dollars) Quantity 1060 1065 1960 1965 8331850 01.0 81.1 600.2 52.1 8380880 180.0 78.7 321.5 721.1 8205000 ‘06 8 83.8 1,073.0 1,136.1 8207103 001.5 728.0 ,870.8 20,917.9 8312000 83.7 220.0 602.0 2,099.5 8380121 5,666.8 2,013.0 175,528.5 “8,603.5 8381130 3.» 7.3 75.8 37.2 8380180 172.3 1,717.6 0,735 6 0,305.3 8380938 130.1 2,507.0 005.0 7,977.9 8310100 30.0 106.6 575.0 1,030.9 8205000 100.7 V8.5 2,812.7 1,651.9 3380921 1,012.7 170.0 12,258.0 211.9 3050150 11.0 800.6 7.5 306-0 2220020 0,935.3 160.8 200.6 120.0 2210070 17.1 00.0 117.1 92.1 2301000 321.8 101.0 6,200.0 2,019.2 2305 00 1,128.3 500.1 17,071.0 15,570.9 0137600 ,205.8 2,831.3 0,020.0 0,095.7 3851 00 08.5 663.6 93.5 801.1 8000720 ‘"6.5 838.0 251.5 211.3 8100100 1,~10.7 1.6 1,856.1 1.0 80708r0 87.0 01.0 10.2 0.3 8380285 3.0 8.0 2.2 5.3 2270000 -,0“5 5 0,032.7 <98.2 677.9 2280300 7 3 8.0 0.6 3.1 2280180 021.0 868.6 00.8 85.0 8722200 11.3 7.5 10.2 0.3 2275000 1,121.2 0,972.1 780.0 958.3 2210070 17.1 00.0 117.1 93.1 8721200 1,026.0 3,602.0 6.0 101.7 87220100 3,580.0 6,362.2 200.3 067.2 8725 600 5,311.3 9,763.5 055.0 2,250.0 8730100 32.0 55.0 77.9 173.7 8031200 8.5 6.2 7.3 0.6 8002300 86.5 00.9 2.7 3.0 8020390 87.0 609.7 203.7 556.7 8001300 105.6 101.0 07.1 51.8 8020010 133.8 3 .9 719.2 211.1 8330700 308.7 150.7 0,865.2 2,713.9 8330500 251.5 065.5 1,293.0 2,305.2 8719900 108.5 155.5 607.2 612.8 8335000 3,011.1 0,521.3 106.2 233.5 8330000 2,330.6 2,625.2 17,152.1 21,531.5 8302000 119.1 115.1 601.8 719.0 8303000 186.5 276.7 9,175.6 10,789.0 8350000 219.2 026.3 5,560.1 9,590.7 8380615 1,856.2 265.9 09.8 5.3 8300000 1,020.8 2,075.7 1,800.0 2,807.1 8380560 1,065.7 1,855 0 607.3 006.6 8130800 2.7 2.0 0.8 0.6 8380305 25.0 01.0 03.2 73.7 8010360 603.0 111.9 11,210.1 2,832.9 8000680 23.5 5.0 153.2 3.0 8000770 1,186.7 2,169.3 092.3 1,172.0 8380360 21.0 132.5 25.2 67.3 8000700 216.2 810.2 120.1 017.3 1143 9800750 9820100 O\O\CD\J 632. 155. 317. 1M7. TAP; '< l." 1 2:011111131311? ( 1 1—1 ,_ 11:73-71 “1391113) ”11w Jchedulc A No. (t‘ 1 mu] 3? dollar ) Quantity 13a3 1965 1360 1935 9163110 ‘.1 18 2 312.1 650.6 9163330 17 7 13.6 53 2 50.7 9070130 18 3 ”5 8 0.5 5.1 9970100 ~3 * E 5 7 9.9 9970130 8 13 1 0.1 0.1 9970920 3. 13 3 2.6 10.7 9070530 7 3 31 8 5.0 20.1 1973113 7 1 5.7 7.3 1373113 3 3 3 3.3 0.2 9970373 1,- 3 3 57' 3 31a 9 157.5 3170010 ' .3 f” 59.8 69.5 9590‘00 13.? l? 9 1.7 2.0 9590250 A E H 3.1 0.2 3730030 -,1:‘ 167 2 1,51".7 66.5 0735303 1, 7 6 0 3,296.9 623.6 901951: ? 3 332 3 33,170.6 20,5U7.9 5853113 1,‘71 0 3,355 7 U,313 6 6,651.5 9260050 1,11 .1 :,8~3 7 9.9 10.0 9260900 611 7 1,666.9 0.1 2.1 921M500 '32.1 120.8 28.1 8.3 7100230 6L2.9 1,890.3 103 7 27u.8 9780510 6.8 2 9 5.3 2.0 9790000 1.3 1.0 0.1 0.1 9790800 9.3 17.8 0.2 1.1 9001100 855.3 699.3 87u.7 1,6u3.9 9010000 1,850.3 1,605.2 12,006.3 11,081.3 9800160 519.6 529. 3,358.6 2,885.2 9800190 1,552 0 ,889 1,650.7 3,897.9 5 u ._1; 11111 TAiLE B.lB.——Cdn3da (metals). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial '71‘ O f n Production Domestic .nirj m v3lume n . Country lariff Index uUDDllGFS a . " nunoliers (1969=100) 1 1955....1 35.11 83.03 96.;8 92.90 1.20 11 01.76 8 .00 37.09 92.70 1.20 111 35.01 87.00 36.67 93.10 1.20 IV 36 97 89.03 35.70 99.00 1.20 1356....1 39 03 91.30 130.02 90.20 1.20 11 30.10 91.33 39.89 95.20 1.20 111 38.70 70.30 93.36 96.00 1.20 17 93.71 36.00 97.83 97.20 1.20 1957 1 95.00 96.03 131.11 98.60 1.20 T ”7.93 9u.30 00.63 100.00 1.2 111 33.98 93.03 39.00 100.70 1.20 17 33.35 93.03 39.50 100.20 1.20 1958 1 39.68 90.00 93.10 100.00 1.90 II 38.33 9:.30 33.33 100.10 1.20 111 31.91 92.03 99.00 103.10 1.20 17 3A.73 90.33 99.19 99.90 1.20 1959. 1 39.09 96.33 101.16 99.60 1.20 11 95.83 99.30 131.18 99.u0 1.20 111 37.37 99.03 131.18 99.00 1.20 17 33.81 133.03 101.61 99.60 1.20 1963....1 93.80 132 00 101.30 100.00 1.20 11 93.28 130.00 130.80 100 50 1.20 111 31.30 33 03 101 00 100 33 1 20 17 35.08 10 .03 102.01 39.30 1 2« 1961 .1 37.82 99 00 132 25 98 20 1.20 11 37.56 102.00 103.71 97.10 1.20 111 29.92 136.00 103 90 96 90 1.20 17 35.95 108.00 102. 6 97 80 1.20 1562 .1 37.13 139.00 131.52 98 50 1.17 11 05.07 112.00 100.91 99.10 1.17 111 33.50 110.00 100.70 99 30 1.17 IV 00.27 115.00 100.81 99 20 1.17 1963 1 03.08 117.00 101.00 99.10 1.17 11 95.59 119.00 101.10 99 00 1.17 111 37.31 121.00 100.91 99.20 1.17 IV 07.11 125.00 100.60 99.50 1.17 1960....1 53.07 129.00 103.01 99.80 1.17 11 53.66 131.00 102.70 100 10 1.17 111 u5.7u 133.00 102.09 100.30 1.17 1v 51.28 130.00 102.u9 100 30 1.17 1965....1 53.75 138.00 105.10 100.00 1.17 11 60.53 101.00 105.52 99.60 1.17 111 55.99 199.00 10u.89 100.20 1.17 1v 70.27 108.00 103.1u 101.90 1.17 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol XiJ PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi PC 105 TABLE b.lU.-—Canad3 (wood and nwrer). Relative Price Variables (U.S. orice relative to) l1.) 1.1t’l7 l . aflhnrt g, iu ;. W m1 “in Third . n H.) '3 4L1‘Z‘A V I”) 1.»:;' [.1 V Volume . ’ f . Country Tariff . . . Index uUDDllePS n (miilionS) (13 q_ 33) Hubbliers ). -A"- ‘J 1955....1 36.20 82.33 38.06 92.36 1.08 11 30.71 a: 33 98.27 93.10 1.08 111 33.07 87.33 38.85 93.77 1.08 17 33 33 89.33 96.91 90.57 1.08 1956....1 27.87 91.03 98.23 95.56 1.08 11 35.78 3; 33 97.68 96.70 1.08 111 35.60 95.33 96.8 96.98 1.08 17 35.11 06.00 95.67 96.19 1.08 1957. .1 33.55 96.30 130.00 95.33 1.08 11 31.81 90.03 98.90 90.51 1.08 111 33.63 93 03 98.31 90.60 1.08 7 33.32 93.30 89.83 ,5.81 1.08 195 ..... 1 31.79 91.33 133.13 96.90 1.08 11 31.68 93.33 133.33 7.83 1.08 111 3?.Li 12.30 133.33 98.23 1.08 17 33.53 90 1 133. 0 98.33 1.08 1059....1 30.70 36 33 131.01 98.09 1.08 11 35.19 39.00 101.6 98.69 1.08 111 01.55 13.00 131.61 98.99 1.08 17 38.08 130.00 131.01 99.33 1.08 1960. 1 37.10 132.6t 101.83 99.20 1.08 11 35.33 133.03 131.29 98.81 1.08 111 32.03 39 13 131.50 99.70 1.08 17 3: 33 113 03 132.52 102.12 1.08 1961....1 3 .70 99.03 100.61 100.38 1.08 11 35.05 132 00 101.75 106.09 1.08 111 35 15 106 03 101.96 107.95 1.08 17 30.90 108.00 101.02 108.69 1.08 1962 .1 38.63 109.00 131.52 109.75 1.05 11 35.00 112.00 100.91 111.20 1.05 111 32.87 110.00 130.70 111.78 1.05 17 31.09 115.00 130.81 111.09 1.05 1963 .1 30.02 117.00 100.10 111.50 1.05 11 30.55 119 00 100.20 111.72 1.05 111 32.00 121.00 100.00 111.79 1.05 17 33.90 125.00 99.70 111.86 1.05 1960....1 00.20 129.00 99.20 111.82 1.05 11 35.60 131.03 98.90 111.89 1.05 111 35.80 133.00 98.70 111.96 1.05 1v 00.39 130.00 ' 98.70 112.26 1.05 1965....1 00.67 138.00 98.10 112.90 1.05 11 01.03 101.00 98.09 113.66 1.05 111 02.08 100.00 97.90 113.17 1.05 1v 00.00 108.00 96.27 111.08 1.05 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol x13 PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi PC 1“6 TABLE B.15.--Un1ted Kingdom (chemicals). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Irnhistriil Exnort . 3 . Third Volume Production Eomebtic Country Tariff (million“) Index ' oupoliers Quonlier" ” (1960=100) “ - ° 1955....1 15.29 86.00 111.56 82.36 1.10 II 15.18 86.00 112.82 82.32 1.10 III 13.1“ 87.00 111.“9 83.22 1.10 IV 12.87 89.00 109.2 8“.10 1.10 1956....1 10.79 87.00 109.28 86.10 1.10 II 12.33 86.00 107.26 88.05 1.10 III 11.10 86.00 105.9“ 90.01 1.10 IV 10.33 86.00 105.26 92.00 1.10 1957....1 12.0“ 87.0 105 12 93 00 1.10 II 10.96 88.00 10“ 0“ 95 01 1.10 III 12.00 90.00 103 22 96 01 1.10 IV 12.“2 88.00 102 6“ 96 01 1.10 1958....1 13.58 88.00 102.70 95 00 1.10 II 15.58 87.00 101.73 95.00 1.10 III 12.95 87.00 101 35 95 00 1.10 IV 15.83 88.00 101 '2 95 01 1.10 1959....I 13.20 88.00 101 20 9“ 09 1.10 11 17.73 91.00 101 17 95 0“ 1.10 III 17.9“ 93 00 101 00 95 0“ 1.10 IV 19.09 98.00 100 66 98.01 1.10 1960....I 2“.80 100.00 100.71 100.00 1.10 II 2 .“0 100.00 100.72 100.00 1.10 III 2 .00 100.00 100.21 100.00 1.10 IV 26.“0 100.00 99.18 100.00 1.10 1961....I 2“.36 101.00 97.12 101.00 1.10 II 21.09 101.00 96.19 103.0“ 1.10 III 20.10 101.00 95.67 103.0“ 1.10 IV 20.10 99.00 95.5“ 103 01 1.10 1962....1 20.69 100.00 93 75 103.01 1.08 II 2 .30 101.00 93.39 101.01 1.08 III 21.39 102.00 93 12 102.01 1.08 IV 2“.26 100.00 92.95 102.01 1.08 1963....1 25.10 100.00 91.7“ 103.01 1.08 II 39.70 103.00 91.79 102.01 1.08 III 29.00 107.00 91.31 101.01 1.08 IV 30.70 109.00 90.29 102.0“ 1.08 196“....I 3“.“6 111.00 89.8“ 103.0“ 1.08 II 33.56 112.00 89.22 10“.09 1.08 III 36.93 113.00 88.“1 105.16 1.08 IV “2.23 115.00 87.“1 107.16 1.08 1965....I 29.67 116.00 87.31 109.16 1.08 II “0.95 116.00 86.50 110.25 1.08 III “2.95 117.00 85.59 110.25 1.08 IV “2.00 118.00 8“.59 110.25 1.08 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol X J P Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) 1 J Pdi Pc 1“7 TABLE B.16.--United Kingdom (machinery). _,___.." '.__ ._~ Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export 7 _ Third Volume Production Domestic Country Tariff (millions) Index Suppliers Suppliers ° (1960:100) 1955....I 28.00 86.00 10“.82 9“.98 1.30 II 37.18 86.00 10“.79 95.09 1.30 III 26.51 87.00 103.56 95.89 1.30 IV 33.56 89.00 101.“2 96.18 1.30 1956....I 2“.“9 87.00 105.08 97.97 1.30 II 28.00 86.00 103.1“ 98.67 1.30 III 25.93 86.00 101.87 99.03 1.30 IV “2.72 86.00 101.22 99.0“ 1.30 1957....I 37.“2 87.00 105.23 98.99 1.30 II 31.28 88.00 10“.l“ 99.22 1.30 III 26.32 90.00 103.32 99.“5 1.30 IV 29.79 88.00 102.75 98.61 1.30 1958....1 26.8“ 88.00 101.37 97.52 1.30 II 26.“2 87.00 100.“1 96.36 1.30 III 26.7“ 87.00 100.0“ 95.98 1.30 IV 26.25 88.00 100.21 97.“0 1.30 1959....I 27.73 88.00 102.“2 98.72 1.30 II 3“.7“ 91.00 102.39 99.02 1.30 III 26.39 93.00 102.21 98.8“ 1.30 IV 28.28 98.00 101.87 100.19 1.30 1960....1 36.20 100.00 101.82 100.68 1.30 II 81.70 100.00 101.83 100.31 1.30 III 70.50 100.00 101.31 99.83 1.30 IV 81.90 100.00 100.27 99.2“ 1.30 1961....I 57.“3 101.00 98.69 99.63 1.30 II 63.07 101.00 97.7“ 99.07 1.30 III 52.67 101.00 97.25 98.57 1.30 IV 56.37 99.00 97.08 99.09 1.30 1962....I 58.33 100.00 96.15 98.78 1.22 II 59.“0 101.00 95.79 96.59 1.22 III 56.3“ 102.00 95.51 96.89 1.22 IV 60.20 100.00 95.33 95.83 1.22 1963....I 66.67 100.00 95.36 95.82 1.22 II 65.25 103.00 95.“2 9“.05 1.22 III 58.30 107.00 9“.9l 92.28 1.22 IV 7“.90 109.00 93.85 91.“l 1.22 l96“....I 88.22 111.00 95.51 91.77 1.22 II 96.2“ 112.00 9“.85 90.91 1.22 III 89.80 113.00 93.98 90.1“ 1.22 IV 106.50 115.00 - 92.92 91.22 1.22 1965....I 98.19 116.00 9“.02 92.21 1.22 II 120.10 116.00 9“.02 91.“9 1.22 III 101.71 117.00 92.17 90.7“ 1.22 IV 132.38 118.00 91.09 89.98 1.22 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol X J P Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) i J Pdi Pc l“8 TABLE B.l7.—-United Kingdom (textiles). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export Third Volume Production Domestic Country Tariff . 3 Index Suppliers (millions) (l960=100) Suppliers .'._ . 11"" 1955....1 30.82 86.00 117.56 116.7u 1.u2 11 15.06 86.00 117.2u 116.“3 1.u2 111 8.02 87.00 115.87 115.06 1.u2 IV 9.02 89 00 113.“8 112.69 1.55 1956....1 10.3u 87.00 108.39 110.50 1.92 II 1u.33 86.00 106.39 1o8.u6 1.u2 III 25.71 86.00 105.08 107.12 1.u2 1v 5u.02 86.00 10“.“1 106.uu 1.u2 1957....1 6“.19 87.00 101.96 105.55 1.u2 II “3.51 88.00 100.90 103.92 1.u2 III 30.8“ 90.00 100.11 100.53 1.u2 1v 37.37 88.00 99.55 96.88 1.u2 1958....1 32.00 88.00 103.82 95.13 1.u2 11 26.21 87.00 102.8“ 9u.23 1.u2 III 13.79 87 00 102.u6 9“.89 1.92 1v 15.83 88.00 102.63 97.08 1.u2 1959....1 12.16 88.00 101.61 96.1“ 1.u2 11 13.90 91.00 101.58 98.1u 1.u2 111 13.09 93.00 101.u0 97.97 1.u2 IV 27.78 98.00 101.07 99.66 1.u2 1960....I “3.90 100.00 102.02 100.51 1.u2 II 26.30 100.00 102.03 100.52 1.u2 III 22.90 100.00 101.51 101.01 1.u2 1v 32.60 100.00 100.u7 98.98 1.u2 1961....1 36.““ 101.00 97.71 98.03 1.u2 II 19.90 101.00 96.77 97.50 1.u2 111 21 39 101 00 96 2“ 97 37 1.u2 IV 20 78 99.00 96.11 95 19 1.u2 1962....1 18.“3 100.00 96.73 9u.83 1.33 11 16 70 100 00 96 36 96 “7 1.33 111 I“ 71 100 00 96 08 96 28 1.33 IV 1u.75 100.00 95.50 96.22 1.33 1963....1 20.78 100.00 95.7“ 96.27 1.33 II 23 17 103 00 95 80 95 76 1.33 III 26 80 107 00 95 29 95 63 1.33 IV 29.50 109.00 9“ 22 95 70 1.33 196“....I 28.“2 111.00 99.03 95.96 1.33 II 29 u1 112 00 93 38 96 91 1.33 III 29 90 113 00 92 52 97 62 1.33 IV 30.39 115.00 - 91 “8 96.62 1.33 1965....1 35.05 116.00 90.62 95.72 1.33 II 38 00 116.00 89 96 95.59 1.33 III 38.38 117.00 89.01 95.3u 1.33 IV “2.10 118.00 89.97 95.30 1.33 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol xiJ PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi Pc l“9 TABLE B.18.--United Kingdom (wood and paper). 1 J 1 i 1 Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Ex ort . 2 Third Vogume Production Egme”FiC" Country Tariff (millions) Index ouppllern Suppliers (1900=100) . 1955....1 16.35 86.00 100.16 103.21 1.10 II 1“.“7 86.00 99.90 103.25 1.10 III 16.63 87.00 98.72 103.3“ 1.10 IV 16.2 89.00 96.60 103.“5 1.10 1956....I 1“.2 87.00 102.76 103.37 1.10 II 12.00 86.00 100.86 102.22 1.10 III 11.98 86.00 99.62 101.10 1.10 IV 11.63 8 .00 102.00 100.00 1.10 1956....I 1“.“1 87.00 106.39 100.00 1.10 II 13.“0 38.00 105.29 98.9“ 1.10 III 13.“? 90.00 10“.“6 98.95 1.10 IV 12.95 88.00 103.88 98.95 1.10 1958....1 11.“7 88.00 101.16 100.00 1.10 II 1“.00 87.00 100.21 100.00 1.10 III 13.05 8 .00 99.83 100.00 1.10 IV 12.81 88.00 100.01 101.0“ 1.10 1959....I 11.13 8-.00 103.“3 103.09 1.10 II 1“.“3 91.00 103.“0 102.06 1.10 III 21.65 93.00 103.22 102.06 1.10 IV 15.35 98.00 102.88 101.01 1.10 1960....1 18.50 100.00 102. 2 100.00 1.10 II 21.10 100.00 102.9“ 100.00 1.10 III 20.60 100.00 102.“1 100.00 1.10 IV 20.2 100.00 101.36 100.00 1.10 1961....I 21.39 101.01 100.2 100.00 1.10 II 20.59 101.00 99.29 98.02 1.10 III 19.31 101.00 99.75 98.02 1.10 IV 17.65 99.00 98.62 99.02 1.10 1962....1 13.82 100.00 98.37 99.02 1.08 II 19.“O 101.00 97.99 99.00 1.08 III l7.“3 102.00 97.71 99.01 1.08 IV l7.“3 100.00 97. 2 99.01 1.08 1963....1 15.“9 100.00 97.36 99.02 1.08 II 17.23 103.00 97.“2 99.01 1.08 III 19.30 107.00 96.90 99.00 1.08 IV 19.70 109.00 95.82 98.00 1.08 196“....I 23.37 111.00 95.61 98.02 1.08 II 22.“8 112.00 9“.23 97.03 1.08 III 21.88 113.00 9“.O8 96.0“ 1.08 IV 21.55 115.00 - 93.01 96.12 1.08 1965....1 22.38 116.00 92.68 96.19 1.08 II 23.“2 116.00 91.82 95.2“ 1.08 III 25.52 117.00 90.85 95.2“ 1.08 IV 28.76 118.00 89.79 95.2“ 1.08 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol X1J PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi PC IfSO TABLE B.19.--European Economic Community (Chemicals). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export - Third Volume PPOduqtion EomeSLiC Country Tariff (millions Inoex “Uppliers Suppliers ” (l960=100) “ 1955....1 1“.71 67.97 108 28 89.00 1.20 II 15.81 70.08 108 8“ 89.00 1.20 III 10.12 72.53 108 O“ 90.00 1.20 IV 13.68 7“.08 107 20 90.00 1.20 1956....I 12.02 72.86 108 87 92.00 1.20 II 1“.56 77.08 108 “3 92.00 1.20 III 13.63 78.59 107 62 92.00 1.20 IV 1“.35 79.20 106 “7 92.00 1.20 1957....1 13.98 80.57 106 01 93.00 1.20 II 16.38 81.08 105 12 93.00 1.20 III 13.37 82.19 10“ 26 9“.00 1.20 IV 17.58 82.09 103 38 9“.00 1.20 1958....I 17.89 83.00 103 05 95.00 1.20 11 19.26 82.2“ 101 83 95.00 1.20 III 16.63 83.28 100 “2 95.00 1.20 IV 22.08 8“.17 101 86 97.00 1.20 1959....1 20.21 85.12 101 77 100.00 1.20 II 17.53 88.31 102 08 99.00 1.20 III 17.01 90.66 101 90 99.00 1.20 IV 17.37 9“.“0 101 20 100.00 1.20 1960....I 2“.00 96.80 100 89 100.00 1.20 II 26.00 99.39 100 51 100.00 1.20 III 2“.70 101.“? 100.03 100.00 1.20 IV 2“.00 103.01 99.“3 100.00 1.20 1961....I 29.01 105.“6 97.75 101.00 1.20 II 26.53 105.95 97.20 99.00 1.20 III 30.59 107.56 96.71 99.00 1.20 IV 28.1“ 109.63 96.27 101.00 1.20 1962....I 27.06 111.95 9“.“2 101.00 1.18 II 26.u0 113.00 9u.18 99.00 1.18 III 25.9“ 115.33 93.53 100.00 1.18 IV 2“.65 115.80 92.51 100.00 1.18 1963....1 29.12 115.37 90.“6 101.00 1.15 II 26.93 120.53 89.67 100.00 1.15 III 3“.80 122.“9 88.86 99.00 1.15 IV 27.30 125.18 88.03 98.00 1.15 l96“....I 32.57 127.85 87.86 99.00 1.15 II 36.53 127.7“ 87.0“ 98.00 1.15 III “5.9“ 127.00 86.30 97.00 1.15 IV “8.06 130.00 85.6“ 99.00 1.15 1965....I 59.62 131.“8 85.71 101.00 1.15 II 55.62 133.“1 85.0“ 100.00 1.15 III 58.“8 133.0“ 8“.35 100.00 1.15 IV 51.81 136.8“ 83.6“ 100.00 1.15 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol XiJ PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (l + T) Pdi “If: r ‘VZ—‘T'Tfin‘a—s .... fin 1W v ..a~..- 15]. TABLE B.20.--European Economic Community (machinery). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export 6 Third Volume Production Domestic Country Tariff (millions) Index Suppliers Oup 11ers ” (l960=100) ° -p 1955....I 111.76 67.97 95.88 95.88 1.25 II 110.9“ 70.08 95.98 9“.“1 1.25 III 90.81 72.53 95.66 9“.01 1.25 IV 108.97 7“.08 9“.85 9“.00 1.25 1956....I 129.32 72.86 100 17 93.05 1.25 II 113.67 77.08 99.76 92.“6 1.25 III 9“.73 78.59 99.03 91.“2 1.25 IV 123.“8 79 20 97.96 89.96 1.25 1957....I 128.“9 80.57 103 99 88.89 1.25 II 133.19 81.08 103 12 88.21 1.25 III 127.37 82.19 102 27 90.13 1.25 IV 117.37 82.09 101 “1 95.61 1.25 1958....I 119.26 83.00 102 75 93.02 1.25 II 122.00 82.2“ 101 53 90.65 1.25 III 9“.95 83.28 100 12 88.98 1.25 IV 105.95 8“.l7 101 56 90.15 1.25 1959....1 93.“0 85.12 10“ 01 99.31 1.25 II 10“.02 88.31 10“ 33 100.67 1.25 III 97.“2 90.66 10“ l“ 9“.55 1.25 IV 135.35 9“.“0 103 “3 97.3“ 1.25 1960....I 171.50 96.80 103 10 96.91 1.25 II 206.90 99.39 102 72 98.32 1.25 III 216.“0 101.“7 102 23 10“.68 1.25 IV 189.“0 103.01 101 62 100.03 1.25 1961....I 19“.06 105.“6 100 91 95.“7 1.25 II 257.52 105 95 100 3“ 93.93 1.25 III 191.“9 107 56 99 83 90.38 1.25 IV 219.31 109 63 99 38 88.72 1.25 1962....I 267.9“ 111 95 99.07 90.05 1.23 II 268.30 113 00 98.81 88.61 1.23 III 202.38 115 33 98.1“ 87.83 1.23 IV 227.“3 115 80 97.07 88.65 1.23 1963....1 236.57 115 37 96.01 88.5“ 1.20 II 263.96 120 53 95 17 85.70 1.20 III 228.80 122 “9 9“ 31 8“.97 1.20 IV 262.20 125 18 93 “2 9“.50 1.20 196“....I 298.12 127 85 93 “9 85.65 1.20 II 288.32 127 7“ 92 62 83.09 1.20 III 23“.36 127 00 91 83 8“.“8 1.20 IV 263.30 130 20 91 13 85.“9 1 20 1965....I 301.1“ 131 “8 90 98 88.18 1.20 II 382.10 133 “1 90.27 87.52 1.20 III 285.90 133.0“ 89.53 86.95 1.20 IV 371.71 136.8“ 88.78 88.22 1.20 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol xiJ PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi Pc ”‘3 . A «$- 7 7'" 1' 'H “Is—— ‘EITT _, . :v ”.25. 2152 TABLE B.2l.-—European Economic Community (metals). ' _‘ .‘.'..'_ 2. u—. —.- ‘ Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export a Third Volume Production Pomestic Country Tariff (millions) Index Suppliers Suppliers ” (l960=100) - 1955....I 78.“7 67.97 9“.98 102.50 1.1“ II 95.06 70.08 95.09 102.78 1.1“ III 62.56 72.53 95.89 10“.2“ 1.1“ IV 83.22 7“.08 96.18 106.90 1.1“ 1956....1 90.56 72.86 97.97 109.58 1.1“ II 79.““ 77.08 98.67 112.28 1.1“ III 63. 2 78.59 99.02 113.7“ 1.1“ IV 72.07 79.20 99.0“ 113.90 1.1“ 1957....1 81.08 80.57 98.99 115.62 1.1“ II 79.79 81.08 99.22 118.88 1.1“ III 78.11 82.19 99.“5 117.21 1.1“ IV 62.00 82.00 98.61 110.72 1.1“ 1958....I 5“.95 83.00 97.52 10“.58 1.1“ II 55.37 82.2“ 96.36 98.82 1.1“ III “6.92 83.28 95.98 96.86 1.1“ IV 61.67 8“.17 97.“0 98.61 1.1“ 1959....1 33.“0 85.12 98.72 99.38 1.1“ II 32.16 88.31 99.02 99.13 1.1“ III 29.07 90.66 98.8“ 99.17 1.1“ IV 15.86 9“.“0 100.19 99.“9 1.1“ 1960....1 “0.50 96.80 100.68 99.9“ 1.1“ II 85.30 99.39 100.31 100.50 1.1“ III 87.“0 101.“7 99.83 100.29 1.1“ IV 80.10 103 01 99.2“ 99.31 1.1“ 1961....1 80.50 105.“6 99.63 98.37 1.1“ II 66.63 105.95 99.07 97.52 1.1“ III 51.88 107.56 98.57 97.22 1.1“ IV 50.39 109.63 99.09 97.“8 1.1“ 1962....1 “2.“5 111.95 98.78 98.1“ 1.11 II “8.“0 113.00 96.59 99.19 1.11 III “7.92 115.33 96.89 98.10 1.11 IV “0.59 115.80 95.83 9“.98 1.11 1963....I 30.78 115.37 95.82 92.03 1.11 II “3.27 120.53 9“.05 89.21 1.11 III 39.50 122.“9 92.28 88.37 1.11 IV “1.50 125.18 91.“1 89.“2 1.11 196“....I “3.17 127 85 81.77 90.08 1.11 II “5.“5 127.7“ 90.91 90.35 1.11 III “8.12 127.00 90.1“ 90.27 1.11 IV “6.12 130.20 91.22 89.85 1.11 1965....I “6.80 131.“8 . 92.21 89.35 1.11 II “6.95 133.“1 91.“9 88.3“ 1.11 III “7.71 133.0“ 90.7“ 86.68 1.11 IV “9.81 136.8“ 89.98 85.0“ 1.11 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol xiJ PJ Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) Pdi PC 1553 TABLE B.22.-—European Economic Community (miscellaneous). Relative Price Variables (U.S. price relative to) Industrial Export . a Third Volume Produgilon Eogiiticg Country Tariff (millions) (1968:180) “” 198‘ Suppliers 1955....1 3“.00 67.97 110.7“ 111.58 1.16 II 29.“1 70.08 110.86 111.68 1.16 III 19.53 72.53 110.“9 110.33 1.16 IV 28.39 7“.08 109.55 106.“7 1.16 1956....1 “0.56 72.86 107.9“ 110.16 1.16 II 32.22 77.08 107.55 107.57 1.16 III 18.79 78.59 106.75 108.18 1.16 IV 23.0“ 79.20 105.60 102.5“ 1.16 1957....I 30. 2 80.57 102.82 106.36 1.16 II 3“.0“ 81.08 101.96 103.95 1.16 III 30.53 82.19 101.12 10“.50 1.16 IV 27.89 82.09 100.26 103.86 1.16 1958....1 25.37 83.00 103.16 102.83 1.16 II 29.05 82.2“ 101.93 100.82 1.16 III 18.2 83.28 100.52 99.01 1.16 IV 23.““ 8“.17 101.96 99.“0 1.16 1959....I 22.“7 85.12 103.70 99.“3 1.16 II 21.13 88.31 10“.02 99.50 1.16 III 22.2 90.66 103.83 97.81 1.16 IV 21.62 9“.“0 103.13 97.79 1.16 1960....I 22.80 96.80 99.98 100.98 1.16 II 2“.30 99.39 99.61 100.77 1.16 III 2“.00 101.“7 99.13 99.92 1.16 Iv 27.00 103.01 98.5“ 98.“3 1.16 1961....I 30.50 105.“6 102.“9 97.“0 1.16 II 30.20 105.95 101.91 9“.13 1.16 III 28.“2 107.56 101.“0 91.95 1.16 IV 33.“3 109.63 100.93 91.67 1.16 1962....1 31.18 111.95 103.91 90.23 1.13 II 36.50 113.00 103.6“ 87.78 1.13 III 30.20 115.33 102.9“ 86.05 1.13 IV 32.57 115.80 101.81 87.96 1.13 1963....1 ' 36.“7 115.37 103.71 85.80 1.13 II “8.12 120.53 102.80 86.38 1.13 III 39.50 122.“9 101.87 8“.80 1.13 IV “2.80 125.18 100.91 8“.00 1.13 196“....I “5.7“ 127.85 99.22 85.96 1.13 II 52.“8 127.7“ 98.29 85.9“ 1.13 III “3.76 127.00 97.“6 8“.33 1.13 IV 50.39 130.20 96.71 82.21 1.13 1965....1 52.89 131.“8 96.86 83.32 1.13 II 73.90 133.“1 ' 96.11 82.00 1.13 III 6“.76 133.0“ 95.32 81.“3 1.13 IV 70.76 136.8“ 9“.52 81.“8 1.13 Corresponding Variable in estimating equation: Symbol x 3 P Pu.s.i Pu.s.i (1 + T) i J Pdi Pc BIBLIOGRAPHY l5“ BIBLIOGRAPHY 1' Adams, F. 0.; Eguchi,H.; and Meyer-zu-Schlochtern, F. "An Econometric Analysis of International Trade, an Interrelated Explanation of Imports and Exports of OECD Countries." OECD Economic Studies Series. (January, 1969). Almon, S. "The Distributed Lag Between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures." Econometrica, Vol. 33, No. 1, (January, 1965), pp. 178-196. Balassa, B. "Tariff Protection in Industrial Countries: An Evaluation." Journal of Political Economy. (December, 1965). Balassa, B., and Kreinin, M. E. "Trade Liberalization under the 'Kennedy Round:' The Static Effects." Review of Economics and Statistics, XLIX, (May. 1967). pp. 125-137. Ball, R. J., and Marwah, K. "The U.S. Demand for Imports, 19“8—1958." Review of Economics and Statistics, XLIV, No. “, (November, 1962). . Basevi, G. "The Restrictive Effect of the U.S. Tariff." American Economic Review, LVIII, (September, 1968), pp. 8“0-852. . "United States Tariff Structure: Estimates of Effective Rates of Protection of United States Industries and Industrial Labor." Review of Economics and Statistics. (May, 1966), pp. 1“7-l60. Branson, w. H. "A Disaggregated Model of the U.S. Balance of Trade." Staff Economic Studies, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, (February, 1968). Corden, w. M. "The Structure of a Tariff System and the Effective Protective Rate." Journal of Political Economy, (June, 1966), pp. 221-237. 155 Cowden, D. J., and Croxton, F. E. Applied General Statistics, Prentice—Hall, Second Edition, pp. 65“—657. DeVries, B. A. "Price Elasticities of Demand for Individual Commodities Imported into the United States." International Monetary Fund Staff Papers. (April, 1951), pp. 397-“19. Houthaken, H. S., and Mager, S. P. "Income and Price Elasticities in World Trade," Review of Economics and Statistics, (May, 1969), footnote 1. Humphrey, D. American Imports. New York, 1955. Johnson, H. G. "The Cost of Protection and the Scientific Tariff." Journal of Political Economy. (August, 1960), pp0 327—3Q5. Junz, H. B., and Rhomberg, R. R. "Prices and Export Performance of Industrial Countries, 1953—1963." I.M.F. Staff Papers. (July, 1965), pp. 2““-271. Kelly, W. B. "The Expanded Trade Agreements Escape Clause, 1955-1961." Journal of Political Economy. (February, 1962), pp. 37—63. Krause, L. B. "United States Imports and the Tariff." American Economic Review, Proceedings, (May, 1959), pp. 592—551. . "U.S. Imports, 19“7-l958." Econometrica. (April, 1962), pp. 221-238. Kravis, I. "Trade Agreement Escape Clause." American Economic Review. (June, 195“). Kravis, I.; Lipsey, R. E.; and Bourque, P. J. Measuring International Price Competitiveness, National Bureau of Economic Research, A Preliminary Report, Occasional Paper 9“, 1965. Kreinin, M. E. Alternative Commercial Policies, MSU International Business and Economic Studies, 1967. . "0n the Restrictive Effect of the Tariff--A Note on the Use of the Balassa Index." The Manchester School. (January, 1966), pp. 75-80. "Effect of Tariff Changes on the Prices and Volume of Imports." American Economic Review, LI, (June, 1961), pp. 312-32“. 157 Kreinin, M. E. "Price U.S. Tariff Elasticities in International Trade--A Suggested Reconciliation." American Economic Review, LVII, (September, 1967), pp. 891-89“. Meade, J. E. Trade and Welfare, Vol. II. Piquet, H. "Tariff Reductions and U.S. Imports." Foreign Trade Policy, Compendium of Papers, 85th Congress, 2nd Session, Washington, 1958. Rees, A. "Price Level Stability and Economic Policy." The Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth, Compendium prepared for the Joint Economic Committee, Washington, 1958, pp. 651—659. Rhombery, R. R.; Randall, R.; and Boissoneault, L. "Effects of Income and Price Changes on the U.S. Balance of Payments." I.M.F. Staff Papers, IIzI, (March, 196“), pp. 58-12“. Small, A. S. "The Effect of U.S. Tariff Reduction on U.S. Import Volume." MSU Business Topics, Graduate School of Business Administration, (Spring, 1967), pp. “3—53. TATE "1111111 3 1 293 LIB RARIES 58 "111111111