It] :39. 4.... u 3 v. . On . L 44.... u». 1.. I .. ‘!.Lt . , 5 . 4%? p... 1.: :u. mar. . Ens-“h- v..:.-.I., .1 . ‘73 V. .4...h.... 11b in ll... 3.... zln‘iérféx 521'. .. . a 0.3... :?.i w}: :lcviyt-.labuat . . 1x,¢..-o2.:.! :- i.‘........: if». . 3‘?» :12; ‘ (visv- .vb l‘zixl Iv .Iw‘bbvllll It a; 11"».‘013; : . |. .0 .5» I. ,2: age" ._ LIBRARY Michigan §tate Univemty it" .fl .. KN La I: i (t I C O -—~r‘) This is to certify that the dissertation entitled THE EFFECT OF VERTICAL NETWORKS ON CHANNEL GOVERNANCE ADAPTATION: A TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS APPROACH presented by Wesley Alan Pollitte has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Ph.D. degree in Marketing Major %sor’s Signature 7/012 57 / / Date MSU is an affinnative-action, equal-opportunity employer PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5/08 K:IProi/Aoc&Pres/ClRCIDateDue.indd THE EFFECT OF VERTICAL NETWORKS ON CHANNEL GOVERNANCE ADAPTATION: A TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS APPROACH By Wesley Alan Pollitte A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Marketing 2008 ABSTRACT THE EFFECT OF VERTICAL NETWORKS ON CHANNEL GOVERNANCE ADAPTATION: A TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS APPROACH By Wesley Alan Pollitte This dissertation extends transaction cost economics by incorporating a network perspective to investigate the adaptation and safeguarding problems within a vertical network marketing channel. This dissertation extends the transaction cost economics perspective that dyadic relationships are not isolated transactions but are influenced by the network in which they reside and must adapt to structural changes in the network, thereby examining the boundary parameters of transaction cost economics. The adaptation of the governance structure to safeguard the specific assets of the buyer is necessitated by the addition of a new customer by a supplier in the buyer’s supplier network. It is proposed that increased centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network will increase the buyer’s uncertainty and influence the governance decision with the supplier. In addition, the density of the buyer’s supplier network influences the governance decision by allowing the buyer to gather information and reduce the uncertainty caused by the addition of the supplier’s new customer and reduce the governance cost with the individual supplier. The results of this dissertation provide evidence that dyadic relationships are influenced by the network in which they exist, and a deeper understanding of adaptive governance is gained when a network perspective is integrated with transaction cost economics logic. Four conclusions are drawn from the results of this dissertation. First, the transaction cost economics prescriptions of increased transaction asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty, and demand uncertainty in a buyer-supplier dyadic relationship lead to increased vertical coordination with a supplier are supported, providing nomological support and internal consistency of the model. Second, supplier new customers occupying a central position in the industry network increase the future buyer demand uncertainty in low demand uncertainty environments and moderate the dyadic governance concerning buyer asset specificity. Third, in low density buyer supplier networks, buyers increase the degree vertical coordination with the supplier in low buyer demand uncertainty and high buyer technological uncertainty environments. However, buyer supplier network density does not influence the buyer’s degree of vertical coordination with the supplier concerning buyer asset specificity and behavioral uncertainty, indicating that buyers use their networks to reduce uncertainty external to the dyad but address concerns internal to the dyad directly with the supplier. Finally, buyer supplier network density has a significant influence on governance choice. In low density buyer supplier networks, buyers opted for market governance, and in high density buyer supplier networks, buyers choose to continue purchasing form the current supplier when a new customer is added by the supplier. The dissertation concludes with managerial implications and directions for future research. .d In! -' 1-;1. I .c .. Corn/right by Wesley Alan Pollitte 2008 DEDICATION This is dedicated to the memory of my parents: Janet M. Pollitte and William O. Pollitte ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This dissertation would not have been possible without the support of many people. I am deeply indebted to by committee chair David A. Griffith for his guidance and support throughout the many revisions. I would also like to thank the committee members, Roger J. Calantone, S. Tamer Cavusgil, and Kenneth A. Frank for their expert guidance and thoughtful comments. I would like to acknowledge the support of Joseph Sandor for his help in contacting supply chain management professionals for the pre-test portion of this dissertation. In addition, I would like to acknowledge the Institute for Supply Management for providing access to its members in support of this dissertation. I would also like to thank my fellow PhD candidates at Michigan State University for their support and encouragement, especially my officemate Serdar Durmusoglu for all his guidance. Finally, I would like to thank my brother, Robert Pollitte, for all his encouragement and support throughout my tenure in the Ph.D. program. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ............................................................................................................. xi LIST OF FIGURES .......................................................................................................... xii CHAPTER ONE MOTIVATION FOR THE DISSERTATION .................................................................... 1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................ 1 PURPOSE OF THE STUDY ................................................................................................... 5 CHAPTER TWO THEORETICAL BACKGROUND .................................................................................... 7 TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS .................................................................................... 7 Dimensions of Transaction Cost Economics .............................................................. 9 Behavioral Assumptions of Transaction Cost Economics ........................................ 11 Governance Forms .................................................................................................... 15 NETWORK THEORY ........................................................................................................ I 7 Network Definition .................................................................................................... 18 Network Centrality .................................................................................................... 21 Network Density ........................................................................................................ 24 Safeguarding Problem in a Network Context ........................................................... 25 Adaptation Problem in a Network Context ............................................................... 27 SUMMARY ...................................................................................................................... 29 CHAPTER THREE THEORETICAL MODEL AND HYPOTHESES ............................................................ 31 HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT .......................................................................................... 32 Buyer Asset Specificity .............................................................................................. 32 Buyer Performance Ambiguity .................................................................................. 35 Buyer Demand Uncertainty ...................................................................................... 36 Buyer Technological Uncertainty ............................................................................. 38 Supplier New Customer Centrality ........................................................................... 39 Supplier New Customer Centrality (Moderator) ...................................................... 42 Buyer Supplier Network Density ............................................................................... 45 vii CHAPTER FOUR RESEARCH METHOD .................................................................................................... 53 VALIDATION OF VARIABLE MEASURES AND PRE-TEST .................................................. 54 EXPERIMENT METHOD AND DESIGN .............................................................................. 61 Sampling Frame ........................................................................................................ 61 Response Rate ........................................................................................................... 62 Sample Characteristics ............................................................................................. 62 Unit of Analysis ......................................................................................................... 62 Design and Procedure .............................................................................................. 63 DEPENDENT VARIABLE .................................................................................................. 65 Vertical Coordination ............................................................................................... 65 INDEPENDENT VARIABLES ............................................................................................. 66 Buyer Asset Specificity .............................................................................................. 66 Buyer Performance Ambiguity .................................................................................. 66 Buyer Demand Uncertainty ...................................................................................... 67 Buyer Technological Uncertainty ............................................................................. 67 Supplier New Customer Centrality ........................................................................... 68 Buyer Supplier Network Density ............................................................................... 68 CONTROL VARIABLES .................................................................................................... 69 Purchasing Frequency .............................................................................................. 69 Relationship Duration ............................................................................................... 69 Industry ..................................................................................................................... 69 Firm Size ................................................................................................................... 69 Gender ....................................................................................................................... 70 CHAPTER FIVE RESULTS ......................................................................................................................... 71 TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS PRESCRIPTIONS ......................................................... 71 Hypothesis One ......................................................................................................... 71 Hypothesis Two ......................................................................................................... 72 Hypothesis Three ...................................................................................................... 72 Hypothesis Four ........................................................................................................ 72 SUPPLIER NEW CUSTOMER CENTRALITY ....................................................................... 73 Hypothesis Five ......................................................................................................... 73 Hypothesis Six ........................................................................................................... 74 Hypothesis Seven ...................................................................................................... 75 BUYER SUPPLIER NETWORK DENSITY ........................................................................... 76 Hypothesis Eight ....................................................................................................... 76 Hypothesis Nine ........................................................................................................ 78 Hypothesis Ten .......................................................................................................... 79 Hypothesis Eleven ..................................................................................................... 81 Viii CHAPTER SIX THEORETICAL AND MANAGERIAL CONTRIBUTIONS OF THE STUDY ........... 83 THEORETICAL CONTRIBUTIONS ..................................................................................... 84 Transaction Cost Economics Prescriptions .............................................................. 84 Network Centrality .................................................................................................... 87 Network Density ........................................................................................................ 89 MANAGERIAL CONTRIBUTIONS ...................................................................................... 93 LIMITATIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTIONS ...................................................... 97 APPENDICES APPENDIX 1: E-MAIL FROM CLINICAL PROFESSOR IN SUPPLY MANAGEMENT SOLICITING SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS PARTICIPATION IN RESEARCH ................ 101 APPENDIX 2:EXECUTIVE SUMMARY SENT To SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS SOLICITING PARTICIPATION IN RESEARCH ......................................... 102 APPENDIX 3: INITIAL E-MAIL SOLICITING SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS PARTICIPATION IN RESEARCH ...................................................................................... 104 APPENDIX 4: FOLLOW-UP EMAIL TO SOLICITING SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS PARTICIPATION m RESEARCH ...................................................................................... 106 APPENDIX 5: RESEARCH QUESTIONNAIRE OF ADAPTIVE RESPONSES USED IN INTERVIEWS WITH SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS ....................................... 107 APPENDIX 6: MEASURES-LITERATURE REVIEW ........................................................... 1 10 APPENDIX 7: PRE-TEST QUESTIONNAIRE SENT TO SUPPLY CHAIN PROFESSIONALS ..... 126 APPENDIX 8: SCRIPT FOR BUYER ASSET SPECIFICITY HIGH AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 129 APPENDIX 9: SCRIPT FOR BUYER ASSET SPECIFICITY Low AND DENsrrY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 132 APPENDIX 10: SCRIPT FOR BUYER ASSET SPECIFICTTY HIGH AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .................................................... 135 APPENDIX 1 1: SCRIPT FOR BUYER ASSET SPECIFICITY LOW AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .................................................... 138 APPENDIX 12: SCRIPT FOR BUYER BEHAVIORAL UNCERTAINTY HIGH AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 141 APPENDIX 13: SCRIPT FOR BUYER BEHAVIORAL UNCERTAINTY Low AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 144 APPENDIX 14: SCRIPT FOR BUYER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY HIGH AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 147 APPENDIX 15: SCRIPT FOR BUYER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY Low AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 150 APPENDIX 16: SCRIPT FOR BUYER TECHNOLOGICAL UNCERTAINTY HIGH AND DENsrrY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 153 APPENDIX 17: SCRIPT FOR BUYER TECHNOLOGICAL UNCERTAINTY LOW AND DENSITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .......................................................... 156 APPENDIX 18: SCRIPT FOR BUYER BEHAVIORAL UNCERTAINTY HIGH AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .................................................... 159 ix APPENDIX 19: SCRIPT FOR BUYER BEHAVIORAL UNCERTAINTY LOW AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTs) TREATMENT .................................................... 162 APPENDIX 20: SCRIPT FOR BUYER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY HIGH AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .................................................... 165 APPENDIX 21: SCRIPT FOR BUYER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY LOW AND CENTRALITY (WITHIN SUBJECTS) TREATMENT .................................................... 168 REFERENCES ............................................................................................................... 232 X LIST OF TABLES TABLE 12 TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS EMPIRICAL STUDIES .................................... 176 TABLE 2: NETWORK CATEGORIES AND EXAMPLES OF RESEARCH ................................... 215 TABLE 32 NETWORK THEORY EMPIRICAL STUDIES .......................................................... 216 TABLE 4: PRE-TEST RESULTS OF TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS AND CONTROL VARIABLES .............................................................................................................. 221 TABLE 52 PRE-TEST RESULTS OF BUYER SUPPLIER NETWORK DENSITY AND SUPPLIER NEW CUSTOMER CENTRALITY ................................................................. 222 TABLE 6: SAMPLE CHARACTERISTICS .............................................................................. 223 TABLE 7: RESULTS-VERTICAL COORDINATION ................................................................ 226 TABLE 8: RESULTS-GOVERNANCE CHOICE ...................................................................... 229 xi LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE 12 INTERCONNECTION OF SUPPLIER IN BUYER NETWORK WITH SUPPLIER NEW CUSTOMER NETWORK ............................................................................................. 171 FIGURE 2: GOVERNANCE COSTS AS A FUNCTION OF ASSET SPECIFICITY ......................... 172 FIGURE 3: CENTRALITY IN A NETWORK ........................................................................... 173 FIGURE 4: VERTICAL NETWORK DENsrrY ........................................................................ 174 FIGURE 5: THEORETICAL MODEL ..................................................................................... 175 xii CHAPTER ONE MOTIVATION FOR THE DISSERTATION Introduction Marketing channel governance has received considerable attention in the marketing literature. Traditionally, marketing channel governance research has relied on transaction cost economics to prescribe the efficient form of governance of an exchange relationship (Geyskens et a1. 2006; Heide 1994; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). The majority of the research has concentrated on the dyadic exchange relationship between the buyer and the supplier. In the last two decades, manufacturers have been moving away from the traditional vertical integration form of governance to a network of autonomous suppliers (Achrol and Kotler 1999; Anderson et a1. 1994). Companies such as General Motors, Boeing, Ford, Microsoft, and IBM have subcontracted activities vital to their production that were once vertically integrated (Lunsford 2007; Stremersch et a1. 2003). Managing a network of suppliers presents buyers with challenges in controlling resources and adapting to changes in the buyer’s supplier network as network membership changes. The prominent focus of research on dyadic exchanges in marketing channel literature to date has led to relatively few studies addressing the influence of network organization in the study of channel governance, and authors have called for research integrating a network perspective with transaction cost economics (Geyskens et a1. 2006; Wathne and Heide 2004; Williamson 1991). Transaction cost economics has been useful in prescribing the structure of interorganizational governance based on the transaction cost of safeguarding transaction r specific assets and adapting to environmental uncertainty (Williamson 1985; 1975). The primary proposition that increasing transaction cost leads to vertical integration has received support in the literature (Geyskens et al. 2006; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). However, transaction cost economics focuses on the dyadic and neglects the influence of other entities in the network. Williamson (1985, p. 393) recognized this limitation, “Although transaction cost economics insistently addresses both ex ante and ex post E- conditions of the contract,. . .it normally examines each trading nexus separately. . .interdependencies among a series of related contracts may be missed or undervalued as a consequence. Greater attention to the multilateral ramifications of T! r.. I A".AI ‘n- contract is sometimes needed.” By considering the influence of the network on dyadic relationships, another dimension is added to our understanding of interorganizational governance. Incorporating a network approach with transaction cost economics allows the consideration of optimizing not just a single relationship but a firrn’s entire network of relationships (Anderson et al. 1994; Geyskens et a1. 2006). Researchers have suggested that to fully understand the dyadic relationship in interorganizational governance, research should incorporate the effect of the network in which the dyadic relationship resides (Achrol 1997; Achrol and Kotler 1999; Anderson et al. 1994; Iacobucci 1996). Research in network governance of marketing channels has begun to address the relationship between dyadic exchange and the influence of network dimensions in buyer-seller relationships. Research applying network analysis to dyadic exchange relationships has investigated channel adaptation (Wathne and Heide 2004), cooperation (Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992), contract enforcement (Antia and Frazier 2001), and stability (Gadde and Mattsson 1987). The results of these empirical studies suggest that the network where the dyadic relationship resides influences the governance of the focal relationship (Powell and Smith-Doerr 1994), but little research has addressed how exchange relationships adapt to changes in network structure to account for uncertainty and safeguarding of assets invested with members of a buyer’s supplier network. This dissertation investigates the adaptation of dyadic interorganizational governance in a network context due to the addition of a new customer by a supplier in a buyer’s supplier network (See Figure 1), thereby extending the analysis of the adaptation and safeguarding problems of transaction cost economics to include a network perspective. The adaptation by organizations to uncertainty in the presence of nontrivial transaction Specific assets is a fundamental prescription of transaction cost economics (Williamson 1985; 1975). Failing to adapt the dyadic governance to account for changes in the network structure surrounding the dyad introduces maladaptation costs (Williamson 1991). Considering network effects on dyadic governance provides an efficient means of acquiring information to reduce governance cost. Supplier networks allow purchasing organizations to access information within the network to enhance innovation (Bell 2005; Zaheer and Bell 2005) and provide flexibility to adapt to technological changes within the market (Balakrishnan and Wemerfelt 1986). The ability to adapt to change in a marketing channel organized as a network of autonomous suppliers represents a departure in managing a marketing channel as a vertical integrated organization. The benefits of a network of suppliers are realized from the ability to access information from members of the network and the flexibility of the buyer to add and subtract members to access the advances in technology (Powell and Smith-Doerr 1994). However, the benefits of the network are countered by the loss of control of information (Oxley 1999; Williamson 1991) and dependence on suppliers (Cook and Emerson 1978). To reap the benefits of a network of suppliers and guard against opportunistic behavior, the buyer must strike a balance between sharing and restricting information with suppliers by adapting governance mechanisms as changes in the network arise. This research postulates that the effect of a supplier in a buyer’s supplier network adding a new customer to the network will be contingent on the centrality of the new customer in the industry network and the density of the buyer’s supplier network. Supplier new customer centrality is the number of organizations an organization can access independently (Freeman 1979) and translates into the influence an organization has within the industry network (Boje and Whetten 1981). The density of the buyer’s supplier network influences the ability of the buyer to access information and is dependent on the extent of interconnection among the organizations of the buyer’s supplier network (Coleman 1988). The network dimensions of centrality and density can have considerable influence on the level of uncertainty concerning the governance between the buyer and supplier (Burt 1992b; Coleman 1988). The addition of the new customer by the supplier may require the buyer to adapt the governance with the supplier due to changes in uncertainty and potential of opportunistic behavior. If the supplier’s new customer’s centrality in the industry network is high, then the level of buyer uncertainty and the threat of information leaking to the new customer will increase, increasing the likelihood the buyer will adapt the governance to reduce uncertainty and safeguard assets. The density of the buyer’s supplier network serves to moderate the uncertainty and potential for opportunism. If the density of the buyer’s supplier network is high, then the buyer can gather information through its supplier network to decrease the uncertainty and detect and sanction opportunistic behavior (Granovetter 1985), decreasing the likelihood of the buyer adapting the governance directly with the supplier. To date, the research of network organization of marketing channels is only beginning to address how dyadic exchange relationships are influenced by other members of a network (Antia and Frazier 2001; Iacobucci 1996; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992; Wathne and Heide 2004). In a study examining the effect of governance in a supply chain, Wathne and Heide (2004) showed that flexibility of downstream customers was dependent on the governance mechanisms of upstream suppliers. The flexible nature of supplier networks introduces a new form of uncertainty into existing dyadic buyer- supplier relationships. Adaptation of the governance structure to this form of uncertainty is a fundamental issue of network marketing channels. Managers of suppliers and buyers alike confront the possibility of having to renegotiate the governance structure of exchange relationships when a supplier in a buyer’s network adds a new customer or incur maladaption costs (Grossman and Hart 1986; Williamson 1991). Purpose of the Study The purpose of this study is to extend transaction cost economics by incorporating a network perspective to investigate the adaptation and safeguarding problems within a vertical network marketing channel. AS highlighted in the introduction, research investigating interorganizational relationships has focused on dyadic exchange. As organizations have increasingly adopted vertical network marketing channels, the importance of understanding the influences of the network on a dyad within the network has grown (Geyskens et al. 2006; Wathne and Heide 2004). Analysis of dyads independent of network influences does not provide a complete understanding of the exchange relationship (Achrol and Kotler 1999; Antia and Frazier 2001 ). This research extends the analysis of the adaptation and safeguarding problems of transaction cost economics. In this research, the adaptation of the governance structure to safeguard the specific assets of the buyer is necessitated by the addition of a new customer by a supplier in the buyer’s supplier network. This research contributes to the literature by extending transaction cost economics by incorporating a network perspective in the analysis of adaptation to unanticipated events of dyadic exchange relationships, thereby examining the boundary parameters of transaction cost economics. As a fundamental paradigm in interorganizational governance, transaction cost economics incorporating network influences provides a greater understanding of exchange relationships in vertical supplier networks where vertical integration is no longer the primary option for controlling transaction costs. This dissertation is organized as follows. Chapter Two provides an overview of the theoretical background of transaction cost economics and network theory. Chapter Three presents the theoretical model and hypotheses. Chapter F our discusses the research design. Chapter Five presents the results. Chapter Six discusses the theoretical and managerial contributions of the research. r." q hmm-lm.}:4-. . I . 1 CHAPTER TWO THEORETICAL BACKGROUND The understanding of the mechanisms of interorganizational governance in marketing has been greatly influenced by transaction cost economics (Geyskens et al. 2006; Heide 1994; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997; Wathne and Heide 2004). Recent research in marketing has begun to extend transaction cost economics by investigating the effect of being embedded in a network on the dyadic relationship (Anderson et al. 1994; Antia and Frazier 2001; Gadde and Mattsson 1987; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992; Wathne and Heide 2004). This dissertation builds on this stream of research by incorporating network effects in transaction cost economic analysis of interorganizational relationships and by investigating how a buyer adapts its governance structure due to the addition of a new customer by one of its suppliers in its supplier network. This chapter first presents an overview of the dimensions and behavioral assumptions of transaction cost economics followed by an overview of network theory. The chapter concludes with a discussion of the influence a network has on the classical safeguarding and adaptation problems advanced by transaction cost economics. Transaction Cost Econ om ics Transaction cost economics has become a dominant paradigm in the literature for explaining interorganizational governance and belongs to the “New Institutional Economics” paradigm (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). Coase (193 7) proposed that the existence of the firm was due to market failure where the firm is able to organize labor and production more efficiently. Building on Coase’s insights, Williamson (1975) proposed the efficiencies of an exchange were determined by the attributes of the transaction and firms economized on the cost of the transaction rather that the cost of production prominent in neoclassical economics. Transactions cost economics takes the View that exchanges are a form of contract between two exchange partners where the transaction is the unit of analysis. Transaction cost economics incorporates the ex ante costs, such as drafting, negotiating, and safeguarding the contract, and ex post costs, such as monitoring and enforcing the contract. Information asymmetry between the exchange parties complicates the organization and execution of the transaction, increasing the transaction cost of the exchange (Dutta et al. 1999). The governance structure is organized around the transaction to minimize cost and reduce information asymmetry to the actors involved (Williamson 1985). The governance structure is either organized as a market transaction, for simple exchanges, or is integrated into the firm, for complex exchanges. A third form of governance, hybrid governance, where the parties remain autonomous but are dependent, has emerged as a form of governance that is intermediate to market and hierarchical forms of governance (Heide 1994; Williamson 1991 ). Transaction cost economics proposes that the dimensions of the exchange determine the most efficient governance structure (Williamson 1985; 1975). Depending on the dimensions of the exchange, transaction cost economics provides a prescription for the choice of governance to minimize transaction cost and exposure to risk. Organizations entering into exchanges are exposed to hazards of opportunism and maladaptation due to an inherent degree of incompleteness of the contract Where all possible contingencies cannot be explicitly known in advance (Grossman and Hart 1986; Williamson 1975). Organizations that enter into these exchanges and invest in ‘10 W“ M transaction specific assets expose themselves to expropriation of these assets and the cost of governance structure misalignment as changes in the external environment occur (Heide and John 1988). As rationale actors, managers of organizations entering into an exchange compare governance structures to minimize the transition costs and choose the most efficient governance form .for managing exposure to hazards of opportunism and maladaptation. According to transaction cost economics, the dimensions of the exchange that determine the governance structure are transaction specific assets, environmental uncertainty, behavioral uncertainty, and transaction frequency (Williamson 1985; 1975). In addition, the behavioral assumptions of the actors engaged in the transaction are opportunism, bounded rationality, and risk neutrality (Williamson 1985; 1975). Table 1 presents empirical studies of transaction cost economics of interorganizational relationships. The four dimensions and three behavioral assumptions will discussed individually next. Dimensions of Transaction Cost Economics. The first dimension is transaction specific assets, or asset specificity. Asset specificity refers toinvestments that are undertaken in support of a particular transaction, the opportunity cost of which investments is much lower in best alternative uses or by alternative users should the original transaction be prematurely terminated (Williamson 1985). Asset specificity is the principle dimension within transaction cost economics. Asset specificity can be in the form of site specificity, physical asset specificity, human asset specificity, and dedicated assets (Williamson 1985). As asset specificity increases, as part of an exchange, the ability to redeploy the assets decreases and the bilateral dependency between parties increases (Heide and John 1988). As transaction specific assets increase, the potential for opportunistic behavior increases and leads to a safeguarding problem to prevent expropriation of the assets or ensure collection of rents generated from the assets. A fundamental proposition of transaction cost economics is when asset specificity increases the cost of managing and safeguarding these assets increases (Williamson 1985; 1975). When the transaction costs exceed the cost of market governance, organizations internalize the exchange since the relative transaction cost of hierarchical governance to manage and safeguard these assets is lower than market governance (Anderson 1985; Heide et al. 1998; Williamson 1985; 1975). The second dimension is environmental uncertainty. Williamson (1985) argues that uncertainty has an influence on the governance structure. He proposes two types of uncertainty, environmental uncertainty which is exogenous to the exchange and behavioral uncertainty which is attributable to human action of the exchange partners. In his classic works, Williamson did not explicitly define environmental uncertainty. Later research, defined environmental uncertainty as unanticipated changes in circumstances surrounding an exchange (Noordewier et al. 1990). Proposing that environmental uncertainty is a multidimensional construct, Walker and Weber (1984) distinguish between demand uncertainty, the inability to accurately forecast the volume requirements, and technological uncertainty, the inability to accurately forecast the technical requirements, as factors that comprise environmental uncertainty. Environmental uncertainty combined with bounded rationality leads to a problem of adaptation due to the incompleteness of contracts to specify all possible contingencies (Grossman and Hart 1986). When asset Specificity is present to a nontrivial degree, environmental uncertainty increases the transaction cost due to the need for renegotiation 10 4| of contracts (Williamson 1985; I975). Transaction cost economics proposes that high levels of environmental uncertainty combined with nontrivial asset specificity will lead to a greater degree of hierarchical governance (Williamson 1985; 1975). The third dimension is behavioral uncertainty. Behavioral uncertainty is defined as the difficulty in ascertaining ex post whether contractual compliance has taken place (Williamson 1985; 1975). Behavioral uncertainty combined with bounded rationality —lfiq' leads to a performance evaluation problem. As behavioral uncertainty increases the cost ni' of monitoring supplier compliance increases, and buyer can exert greater control at a lower cost within the organization to monitor compliance. Transaction cost economics “A “._._ postulates that as behavioral uncertainty increases, in the presence of nontrivial asset specificity, the likelihood of vertical integration increases (Buvik and John 2000; Williamson 1985; 1975). The fourth dimension is transaction frequency. Transaction frequency refers to how often transactions occur between exchange partners. Williamson (1985, p. 60) recognized the importance of transaction frequency and that ‘specialized governance structures are more sensitively attuned to the governance needs of nonstandard transactions than are unspecialized structures.’ For recurring transactions, investments in specialized assets will be easier to recover for larger transactions. Thus, transaction cost economics postulates a conditional effect. If asset specificity is nontrivial, then the cost of hierarchical governance for a high transaction fiequency will be higher than the cost of market governance, leading to hierarchical governance (Williamson 1985; 1975). Behavioral Assumptions of Transaction Cost Economics. The first behavioral assumption of transaction cost economics is bounded rationality. Bounded rationality is 11 the semi-strong form of rationality where economic actors are ‘intentionally rational, but only Iimitedly 80’ (Simon 1961). The semi-strong form stipulates that human minds are limited cognitively and do not have access to all available information. Thus, concerning governance structure decisions, economic actors assign transactions in a discriminating way (Williamson 1985). Bounded rationality when combined with uncertainty, both environmental and behavioral, operates in the ex ante and ex post phases of the exchange. In the ex ante phase, it limits economic actors from writing complete contracts that account for every possible future contingency (Grossman and Hart 1986). In the ex post phase, it creates a performance evaluation problem in regards to contract compliance and adaptation to changes in the external environment. Transaction cost economics postulates that uncertainty, both behavioral and environmental, increases the cost to monitor and adapt contracts will increase, leading to a desire for greater control and a greater likelihood of hierarchical governance (Williamson 1985; 1975) The second assumption is opportunism. Opportunism is defined as ‘self-interest seeking with guile’ (Williamson 1985; 1975). Opportunism is the strong form of self- interest and includes, but is not limited to, blatant forms, such as lying, stealing, and cheating and subtle forms of deceit. Opportunism can be present either ex ante or ex post (John 1984; Wathne and Heide 2000). Ex ante opportunism may involve deliberate misrepresentation, due to information asymmetry, by parties during the negotiation of an exchange, leading to a problem of adverse selection. Ex post opportunism involves violations of the contract over the duration of the agreement, leading to a problem of moral hazard. Transaction cost economics postulates that in situations where asset specificity is nontrivial the cost to protect against opportunism will increase, leading to a 12 desire for greater control and greater likelihood of hierarchical governance (Provan and Skinner 1989; Rokkan et al. 2003; Williamson 1985; 1975). In the study of interorganizational relationships, opportunism emerges as a central construct and is increasingly relevant in the presence of nontrivial asset specificity. In conjunction with the adaptation problem, Williamson (1993) notes that bounded rationality alone would never give rise to the interesting economic organization problems in the absence of opportunism. Without considering opportunism, parties to a contract could adjust to unanticipated disturbances by self-enforcement of agreements and no ex post maladaption problems would arise. However, considering opportunism, where each party will attempt to maximize its position due to unanticipated events introduces substantial governance costs into the organization of interorganizational relationships. Since partners to an exchange are well-socialized, opportunism is not present in each transition; however, transaction cost economics recognizes that a partner may act opportunistically (Williamson 1993). The third assumption is risk neutrality. Risk neutrality is the least studied of the three assumptions. Williamson (1991) conceptualizes risk neutrality as a point where firms are indifferent between market and hierarchy governance, and researchers have interpreted risk neutrality as defined in neoclassical economics (Chiles and McMackin 1996). Contrasting risk neutrality to risk adverse and risk seeking positions, a risk neutral position assumes a position between the two extremes. Chiles and McMackin (1996) propose that the risk position a firm takes will influence the choice of governance relative to the asset specificity leVel. Firms that are risk seeking will continue to transact in the market at higher levels of asset specificity than risk neutral or risk adverse firms, and risk 13 adverse firms will vertically integrate at lower levels of asset specificity than risk neural or risk seeking firms. Extensive empirical studies have been conducted using the transaction cost economics framework in the business disciplines of accounting, finance, marketing, and organizational theory, as well as, law, political science and economics (David and Han 2004; Geyskens et al. 2006; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997; Shelanski and Klein 1995). This body of research has been generally supportive of governance choice being largely determined by the cost of transactions and the characteristics underlying the fiamework. In qualitative studies of the tenants of transaction cost economics (David and Han 2004; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997; Shelanski and Klein 1995), strong support is found for propositions concerning asset specificity and the safeguarding of these assets from opportunistic behavior. Mixed support is offered for the role of governance concerning environmental uncertainty and adaptation and behavioral uncertainty and performance evaluation proposed by transaction cost economies. In a quantitative meta-analysis, Geyskens, Steenkamp and Kurnar (2006) find strong support for the role of governance in asset specificity and the safeguarding problem. The authors find that elevated volume and behavioral uncertainty promote a choice of hierarchal governance over market governance. Conversely, increased technological uncertainty promotes market governance over hierarchical governance, suggesting organizations desire flexibility to adapt to new technology. In addition, the authors suggest that relational governance may be a more suitable alternative than market governance when an organization is confronted with high volume or technological uncertainty if it is embedded in a network that allows a firm the flexibility of using different production facilities and access to alternative 14 technology. The results of these qualitative and quantitative studies, comprised of 30 years of empirical research, demonstrates the usefulness of transaction cost economics as a robust approach for predicting interorganizational governance choice. Governance Forms. Williamson (1985; 1975) originally proposed two forms of governance structure, market and hierarchy, culminating from the attributes of the transaction. A firndamental proposition of this conceptualization is as transaction costs exceed the cost of governing a market exchange, organizations would internalize the exchange in the form of vertical integration. Further refinement of the outcome of exchange led to an intermediate form of hybrid governance, where two organizations engaged in the exchange remained independent but incorporated some of the features of market and hierarchical governance (Williamson 1991). Williamson (1991) argues that the form of governance in a bilateral relationship will be determined by a combination of the transaction specific assets and governance cost arising from adaptation. Figure 2, adopted from Williamson (1991), shows the relationship between asset specificity and governance cost and the resulting governance structure. In this conceptualization, the most efficient governance structure depends on the level of asset specificity invested in the relationship by each of the partners. If k* is the optimal value of k, where k is the level of asset Specificity invested in the exchange relationship, then the efficient level of asset specificity is use markets for k* < k1, use hybrids for k1 < k* < k2 , and hierarchy for k* > k2 . Moving to the right along the curves implies increasing governance cost and escalating application of controls for governing the relationship. Increasing governance costs due to adaptation have the effect of shifting the optimal value of k* to the left, and decreasing governance costs shift the optimal value of k* to the right. For instance, in the 15 Vicinity of k2 , decreases in governance cost would shift k2 to the right, increasing the asset specificity level that hybrid governance would support. Conversely, increases in governance cost would shifi k2 to the lefi, decreasing the asset specificity that hybrid governance would support. The distinguishing characteristics of the three governance structures are the costs of different coordination and control mechanisms and the ability to govern transactions. Accordingly, the governance costs are dependent on the asset specificity of the exchange and the need to protect these assets in the face of uncertainty (Williamson 1991). Uncertainty increases the governance costs due to the threat of expropriation and leakage of information. As expropriation and leakage hazards increase, the amount of transaction specific assets needed to support hybrid governance decreases in favor of hierarchical governance. In other words, as the cost of adapting to uncertainty increases, organizations will tend to favor hierarchical governance as the efficient form of governance for decreasing levels of asset specificity. Heide (1994) further refined the conceptualization of governance structure by providing a typology of market, unilateral/hierarchical, and bilateral governance forms accompanied with the distinguishing features in the imitation, maintenance, and termination phases of the exchange relationship. In a unilateral form of interorganizational governance, the exchange parties remain separate and one party is granted authority to develop rules and make decisions. Disputes are managed internal to the relationship and contracts are used to enforce compliance of the exchange. In bilateral interorganizational governance, exchange parties develop closer ties with overlapping roles and joint responsibilities, providing a framework for subsequent 16 ‘1 “_W‘] J:_AE"T u adaptation through mutual adjustment (Macneil 1980), and agreements are enforced through the use of common interests and expectations of future continuance (Heide and Miner 1992). Network Theory A dyadic relationship between a buyer and a supplier does not exist in isolation impervious to unanticipated external events. An important factor influencing an organization’s environment is the network in which it resides (Powell and Smith-Doerr 1994). The dyad exists as part of a larger network of buyers and suppliers. Conceptually, a network consists of large number of actors and the pattern of relationships that tie them together (Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992). For example, in the automotive industry, U.S. automakers use an extensive network of independent suppliers (Dyer 1996b), ranging from suppliers of standardized components to collaborative research and development (Sako and Helper 1998). Networks contain a multitude of individual dyads linking suppliers to other suppliers and buyers. When a supplier adds a new customer, the dyadic relationship between the supplier and the buyer is influenced by the change to the buyer’s supplier network. The change in the network will introduce uncertainty and the potential for opportunistic behavior if nontrivial asset specificity is present in the dyadic relationship between a buyer and supplier (Antia and Frazier 2001; Wathne and Heide 2004). Accounting for the influence of the network moves transaction cost economics beyond the analysis of discrete exchanges and incorporates a perspective based on the position of other economic actors in a network and the structure of a network. 17 A This section introduces concepts from network theory and the influence these dimensions have on the degree of uncertainty and the potential for opportunism experienced in a dyadic exchange relationship between a buyer and supplier. Specifically, the focus of this section will be on the structural constructs of centrality and density. Where centrality refers to the position an organization occupies in a network, and denotes the extent to which the organization occupies a strategic position in a network by virtue of being involved in many significant ties (Wasserrnan and Faust 1994). Density is the extent of interconnection among the actors of a network (Coleman 1988). An organization’s position in a network (centrality) and structural characteristics of a network (density) affects the firrn’s ability to access information (Gnyawali and , Madhavan 2001) and changes in the position of firms within a network introduces uncertainty to other members of the network (Gadde and Mattsson 1987). This section proceeds with a discussion on the use of network theory in the marketing literature, a definition of networks, the constructs of centrality and density of a network, and the application of network theory to the safeguarding and adaptation problems of transaction cost economics. Network Definition. Originating in the field of sociology, network theory has been used extensively in organizational theory to investigate relationships between individuals and organizations (Parkhe et a1. 2006). In the organizational theory literature, networks have been described as “network organization” (Miles and Snow 1986), “network forms of organization” (Powell 1990), “interfirrn networks” (U zzi 1997; Uzzi 1996) and “quasi-firms” (Eccles 1981). Network theory has grown in its use in the marketing literature (Achrol and Kotler 1999), and has been applied to the structure of 18 marketing organizations (Achrol 1991), dyadic business relationships (Anderson et al. 1994; Antia and Frazier 2001; Gadde and Mattsson 1987; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992; Wathne and Heide 2004), and relationship marketing (Hakansson and Snehota 1995; Iacobucci 1996; Moller and Wilson 1995). In dyadic relationships between buyers and suppliers, networks provide a form of governance structure intermediate to pure market and hierarchical governance (Jones et al. 1997). Network structure influences the power and cooperation within dyads (Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992) and access to information in new product alliances (Rindfleisch and Moorrnan 2001). While the majority of research has focused on the relational or structural aspects of network theory for either coordinating or governing relationships, less research has been directed at the effect networks have in introducing or controlling uncertainty in dyadic relationships. Researchers have urged multi-level analysis of relationships at the firm and network levels to enhance the richness of theory development of dyadic interorganizational relationships (Achrol 1997; Achrol and Kotler 1999; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992). Researchers in the marketing literature have offered varying definitions of network organization (Anderson et al. 1994; Antia and Frazier 2001; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992). Fundamentally, a definition of network organization includes the existence of two or more economic actors and the pattern of ties between the actors. Achrol and Kotler (1999) define a network organization as: An independent coalition of task- or Skill-specialized economic entities (independent firms or autonomous organizational units) that operates without hierarchical control but is embedded, by dense lateral connections, 19 mutuality, and reciprocity, in a shared value system that defines “membership” roles and responsibilities. The definition recognizes the important feature of embeddedness which differentiates it fiom other forms of organization (Granovetter 1985), and the dependence of organizations on other firms in the network connected by either direct or indirect ties (Cook and Emerson 1978). Achrol and Kotler (1999) further distinguish between four types of network organizations: vertical networks, internal networks, intermarket networks, and opportunity networks. The function of each network and examples of research are presented in Table 2. Achrol and Kotler (1999) define a vertical network as: A group of resource firms specializing in the various products, technologies, or services that constitute the inputs of a particular industry, organized around a focal company (sometimes a “virtual” company) that focuses on monitoring and managing the critical contingencies faced by the network participants. In this conceptualization, the network consists of suppliers and distributors organized around a focal firm (buyer). The focal firm performs few manufacturing functions and serves as an “integrator” to organize and coordinate the organizations in the network (Achrol and Kotler 1999). The ability of the buyer to organize the network allows the buyer to change membership of the network to meet the buyer’s needs and sanction members for behavior contrary to the shared expectations of the network (Granovetter 1985; Rowley 1997). 20 A vertical network organized around a focal organization develops a group identity with shared routines, technology, and behavioral expectations (Dyer and Nobeoka 2000). Organizations within the vertical network share technology and develop procedures to transfer knowledge among the members to enhance innovation (Bell 2005; Zaheer and Bell 2005). The vertical network constitutes a resource to the focal organization and a source of competitive advantage in the marketplace (Achrol 1997; Achrol and Kotler 1999). Being a source of competitive advantage, the focal organization may react with a sense of trepidation when suppliers work with organizations outside the network. Suppliers working with organizations outside the network may provide information to their new customers that may erode the competitive advantage of the focal organization. The intrusion of a supplier’s new customer into the network suggests that the focal organization may perceive an increased threat of opportunism and increased uncertainty about the intentions of the new customer. To reduce the threat of opportunism and uncertainty, the focal organization will need to adapt its dyadic relationships with suppliers engaging in sales to organizations new to the network. Network Centrality. Network theory builds on the perspective that economic actions are influenced by the social context in which they are embedded and are influenced by the position of organizations in the network (Gulati 1998). Network theory focuses on informational and control advantages accorded organizations by virtue of their relational1 and structural embeddedness within the network. The relational and structural embeddedness perspectives often overlap, since control advantage can arise from control 1 Relational embeddedness is defined as the ‘personal relationships people developed with each other through a history of interactions.’ 21 of information (Burt 1992b). Relational embeddedness stresses the informational benefits of direct ties for gaining fine-grained information (Krackhardt 1992) where organizations possess common information and knowledge of each other and organizations develop a shared understanding of behavior that influence their actions (Coleman 1988). Structural embeddedness emphasizes the informational value of occupying a position in the network where information flows through not only the individual ties, but also through the network itself (Gulati 1999; Gulati 1995b). Structural embeddedness is defined as the ‘impersonal configuration of linkages between people or units’ (N ahapiet and Ghoshal 1998). The informational benefits of structural embeddedness are dependent on the centrality and density of the network, as measured by the number of ties between organizationsz, where firms with a greater number of ties have access to greater amounts of information (Coleman 1988; Krackhardt 1992). The centrality of an organization and the density of the network capture the informational and control benefits of network position and structure (Coleman 1988; Krackhardt 1992). Table 3 presents empirical studies of network centrality and density. Centrality has been measured as of degree of centrality, closeness, and betweenness (Freeman 1979; Krackhardt 1992; Wasserman and Faust 1994). Degree of centrality is the simplest measure of centralin and refers to the number of ties with other organizations in the network. Freeman (197 9) conceptualized degree of centrality as a measure of activity. From an exchange perspective, the degree measure of centrality represents the number of alternatives available to an organization. Closeness is the Ties between organizations are categorized as either weak or strong ties. The difference In the ties rests on the magnitude and content of information accessed through the ties with other organizations, such as the frequency, intensity, and configuration. 22 organization’s ability to access independently all other members of the network, and provides a measure of how quickly an organization can interact with other firms in receiving and communicating information (Freeman 1979). Closeness is interpreted as a measure of efficiency and the ability to avoid the control of others. Betweenness is the degree to which an organization lies between other organizations (Wasserman and Faust 1994). Betweenness measures the extent to which actors fall between pairs of other organizations on the shortest path connecting them (Freeman 1979) A central organization occupying a position between other organizations has the ability to mediate a communication between other organizations by withholding or distorting information (Burt 1992b). Figure 3 presents a ten organization network (Cook et al. 1983). For closeness and betweenness measures of centrality, organization A occupies the most central location in the network followed by organizations B1, B2, and B3 then organizations C13, Clba C23, C2b, C33, and C31,. Measuring the direct linkages only, the degree of centrality for organizations A and organizations B1, Bz, and B3 are equal but greater than organizations Cla, C11,, C23, C21,, C3a, and C31,. By being situated between organizations B1, Bz, and B3, organization A is able to independently access and mediate information between each of the Bx organizations. Through each of the organizations (B1, Bz, and B3), organization A is also able to indirectly access each of the ny organizations. In this network, organization A has greater access to more sources of information and control of 23 information and is potentially more powerful than the other members of the network (Brass and Burkhardt 1992; Freeman 1979). Centrality is associated with an organization’s status within the network (Podolny 1993). The status of a central organization signals to other members of the network its reputation as a potential exchange partner (Raub and Weesie 1990). The ability to signal to other members of the network reduces uncertainty and search costs when developing relationships with central organizations (Gulati 1995b). Having greater access to information elevates the influence of an organization within the network (Boje and Whetten 1981). A central organization’s influence stems from its position in the network and its ability to broker the flow of valued resources and mobilize resources controlled by others (Raub and Weesie 1990). By being situated between organizations, a central organization has access to unique information from multiple sources (Shan et al. 1994; Van de Ven 1986), thereby enhancing its ability to innovate (Powell et al. 1996) and attract other trustworthy prospective partners (Gulati 19953). Network Density. In addition to centrality, density influences an organization’s ability to access and control information. Coleman (1988) argues networks that are densely embedded with many connections between organizations allow for robust and collective action, convey norms of exchange, and facilitate the accrual of obligations. In high density networks, information and resources spread quickly and efficiently because of the many interconnections and shared routines for information collection and distribution amongst the network’s members (Coleman 1990; Rowley 1997; Valente 1995). As shown in Figure 4, in a dense vertical network, information can be Shared between the Tier 1 suppliers and Tier 2 suppliers without having to involve the buyer. In 24 contrast, in a low density vertical network, information is not shared between the Tier 1 and Tier 2 suppliers and must flow through the buyer. Norms between the exchange partners form patterns of exchange and produce shared behavioral expectations and develop a perception of legitimacy (Galaskiewicz and Wasserman 1989). Dense networks enhance the ability to monitor actions of other firms, coordinate pressure to conform to expectations of other network members, and apply effective sanctions since they amplify the reputation effects of sanctions (Coleman 1990). Safeguarding Problem in a Network Context. The safeguarding problem arises, according to transaction cost economics, due to the deployment of nontrivial specific assets and the possibility that a partner may act opportunistically to exploit those investments (Williamson 1985; 1975). Transaction cost economics proposes that increases in asset specificity lead to increases in the costs to safeguard these assets, and when these costs exceed the cost of purchasing the product in the market, organizations should vertically integrate to safeguard these assets against opportunism hazards (Williamson 1985; 1975). In addition to using vertical integration to govern the exchange, research has shown that relational governance can serve to safeguard transaction specific assets from opportunism in interorganizational relationships where vertical integration may not be possible (Dyer 1997; Heide and John 1992; Heide and John 1988; John 1984). In a vertical network, the history of transactions between firms leads to the emergence of shared values (U zzi 1997) and trust between the organizations increases with greater interaction (Gulati 1995a). As shared values and trust between exchange partners develop, network governance can serve in place of vertical integration (Cannon et al. 2000). 25 Centrality of the organization and the density of the network reduce opportunism in network governance (Coleman 1988; Granovetter 1985). A firm occupying a central location within a network is less likely to act opportunistically due to detrimental effects to its reputation (Raub and Weesie 1990) and is more likely to detect opportunistic behavior due to greater access to information (Walker et al. 1997). Reputational concerns create self-enforcing safeguards and can substitute for contractual safeguards (Bradach and Eccles 1989; Powell 1990), where immediate short-term gains to an organization are offset by loss of reputation and future costs (Williamson 1991). A firm’s reputation signals to other organizations its attractiveness as a potential supplier and its indirect ties serve as a system of referral to screen potential suppliers through other network members with past relationships with the potential supplier (Gimeno 2004; Gulati 1999). A centrally positioned firm can also influence the behavior of other firms within the network due to greater dependence of these organizations on the central firm in the network. In a study of Toyota’s supplier network, Dyer and Nobeoka (2000) found that Toyota is able to influence its suppliers by building strong network identity and coordinating rules. Toyota not only enhances its reputation by managing the network, but also enhances the reputation of the other members in the network. In dense networks where network members are interconnected, information about one member’s opportunistic behavior difiuses rapidly through the network to other members (Granovetter 1985). Dense networks facilitate the emergence of norms (Adler and Kwon 2002) and common behavioral patterns (Coleman 1990). Violations of shared norms are more likely to be detected and sanctions for opportunistic behavior are more easily imposed in dense networks (Walker et al. 1997). Dense networks not only reduce 26 the risk of opportunistic behavior in the focal relationship, due to the threat of reputation loss, but also in relationships with other organizations (Gulati 1995a). In dense networks, common norms develop and improve mutual understanding among the members, lowering the possibility of opportunistic behavior and is key to safeguarding specific assets and substitutes for contractual safeguards (Bradach and Eccles 1989; Jones et al. 1997 ; Kale et a1. 2000). By reducing the likelihood of opportunistic behavior, centrality and network density lower the cost of transaction governance. Occupying a central location allows a firm to access more information efficiently and accords the firm a high status and reputation (Podolny 1993; Williamson 1991). Acts of opportunism in a dense network are transmitted quickly through the network, which diminishes the reputation of centrally located firms. The combination of the potential cost of tarnishing the firm’s reputation and lower cost of obtaining information lower the cost of governance. In network governance, the lower governance cost supports a greater investment in transaction specific assets before the optimal cost of governance would require hierarchical governance (Williamson 1991). Adaptation Problem in a Network Context. Transaction cost economics states that an adaptation problem is created when an organization’s managers, due to bounded rationality, have difficulty in modifying contractual agreements when changes in the external environment occur (Williamson 1985; 1975). The adaptation problem is further complicated in the presence of nontrivial transaction specific asset investments by exchange partners. According to transaction cost economic logic, the solution in conditions of high environmental uncertainty is to vertically integrate to minimize the 27 transaction costs of adapting to the changes in the environment surrounding the exchange (Williamson 1985; 1975). Research has shown that relational governance can also serve to reduce environmental uncertainty and lower the transaction cost of adapting in buyer- supplier relationships (N oordewier et al. 1990). The ability to access information through a network reduces the environmental uncertainty facing the organization and decreases the cost of governing the relationship by decreasing the need to implement hierarchical governance (Gulati 1999). The same attributes of centrality, access to information, influence, and reputation, in a network that limit opportunism, also influence the environmental uncertainty facing an organization. In a study examining the effect of unanticipated events on organizations, Madhavan, Koka, and Prescott (1998) found that centrality was a significant factor in ascertaining the uncertainty concerning the event, suggesting that occupying a central position in the network provides greater access to information. The status of occupying a central location signals to other organizations the firm’s reputation as a potential partner (Podolny 1993). In the selection of partners for alliances, referrals and reputation provide self-selection criteria to limit potential partners for centrally located firms (Gulati 1995b). Having knowledge of prior relationships of a potential supplier’s behavior with other firms reduces the uncertainty in forming a relationship with the firm, lowers search costs, and monitoring costs (Kogut et al. 1992; Powell et al. 1996) A dense network reduces the cost to discover information and lowers search costs (Coleman 1988). Dense networks with many linkages between organizations reduce uncertainty and promote adaptation by increasing communication and information 28 sharing (Kraatz 1998). Organizations in dense networks have access to greater amounts of information than in sparse networks, due to greater interconnectedness between members of the network (Coleman 1988). Networks provide firms with flexibility to manage volatile environments and quickly adapt to changing market conditions by changing links between members in the network (Gulati 1999). Conversely, in sparse networks, information may be clustered in groups, each with divergent information, or the network may lack information, thereby increasing the environmental uncertainty of an organization. Firms reduce their environmental uncertainty by being centrally located within a dense network. By being centrally located, firms have greater access to information and screen potential partners through referral from other partners and self-selection of perspective partners. Using a dense network, organizations can gather information efficiently by using the network to reduce environmental uncertainty. Reducing environmental uncertainty in the transaction, reduces the cost of governance in hybrid interorganizational exchanges, and lower cost of governance increases the investment in transaction specific assets the exchange can support before the optimal cost of governance would require hierarchical governance (Williamson 1991). Summary Transaction cost economics has provided a wealth of information concerning our understanding of the attributes of a transaction that lead to the interorganizational governance structure (David and Han 2004; Geyskens et al. 2006; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997 ; Shelanski and Klein 1995). However, a majority of the research has concentrated on the dyadic relationship as the unit of analysis neglecting factors influencing the focal 29 dyad based on where it resides within a network context. Researchers in marketing have begun to examine the influence of network factors on dyadic exchanges (Anderson et al. 1994; Antia and Frazier 2001; Gadde and Mattsson 1987; Iacobucci and Hopkins 1992; Wathne and Heide 2004), and research has shown that including network factors enhances the understanding of mechanisms influencing the outcomes of dyadic relationships. A source of environmental uncertainty in an interorganizational exchange is a change in the structure of the network in which the dyadic relationship resides. A change in the network causes the governance structure to shift to a state where it is no longer the most efficient form of governance, at which point the partners will seek to adapt the terms of the exchange to a new governance structure to curb the potential for opportunism and reduce maladaptation cost. In Chapter 3, a model of adaptation and safeguarding is developed based on the transaction cost economics paradigm with the inclusion of the constructs of centrality and density from network theory to explain the change in governance structure of a buyer-supplier interorganizational exchange. 30 CHAPTER THREE THEORETICAL MODEL AND HYPOTHESES This study investigates the adaptation of governance structure in buyer-seller relationships. The adaptation problem in transaction cost economics addresses how organizations manage ex post environmental uncertainty (Williamson 1985; 1975). Adaptation to change is a critical issue in the study of interorganizational governance (W illiarnson 1991). This study focuses on the governance of an exchange relationship where the buyer and the supplier are autonomous organizations in a vertical network (Achrol and Kotler 1999). Adaptation of the governance structure is required when an extraneous event causes imbalance in an existing dyadic governance structure introducing maladaption costs (Williamson 1985). A source of environmental uncertainty for the dyadic relationship can be caused by a change in the structure of the network in which the relationship resides. Specifically, for the purpose of this study, the event introducing environmental uncertainty in the dyadic relationship is the addition of a new customer by a supplier in the buyer’s supplier network. The addition of a new customer by a supplier will necessitate that the governance structure between the buyer and the supplier adapt to accommodate the new customer in the buyer’s supplier network. It is hypothesized that the structural characteristics, i.e., centrality of the new customer in the industry network and density of the buyer’s supplier network, will moderate the attributes of the exchange, thereby leading to adaptation of the governance structure. The addition of a new customer by a supplier to the network is analyzed from the perspective of the buyer. Figure 5 presents the model for the adaptation of the governance structure between the buyer and a supplier based on the buyer’s asset 31 specificity, behavioral uncertainty, demand uncertainty, and technological uncertainty. It is hypothesized that centrality of the supplier’s new customer will be positively associated with the buyer’s demand and behavioral uncertainty and will moderate the relationship between buyer asset specificity and governance, and the density of the buyer’s network moderates the relationships of buyer asset specificity, behavioral, demand, and technological uncertainty with governance. Since the buyer’s supplier network is a source of information, the buyer’s access to information will reduce the need for vertical coordination. If the density of the buyer’s supplier network is high, then the buyer can access more information from the network than from a network with a low density, thereby reducing the uncertainty of the buyer. The following section presents the formal hypotheses for buyer asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty, demand uncertainty, and technological uncertainty incorporating the effect of the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network and the buyer’s supplier network density. To provide nomological validity and internal consistency of the model, the transaction cost economic variables are incorporated in the model and later tested in the experimental design. Hypothesis Development Buyer Asset Specificity. Transaction cost economics postulates as a buyer’s investments in transaction specific assets increase, the buyer should increase the degree of vertical coordination with a supplier (Williamson 1985; 1975). In a supplier network, vertical coordination involves the Sharing of proprietary information, such as technical specifications, marketing plans, and product development, with a supplier. Sharing this information with an independent external party, the buyer loses a degree of control over 32 the information shared with the supplier. As the buyer’s investments with the supplier increase, the buyer is at increasing risk of opportunistic behavior on behalf of the supplier and greater vertical coordination is required to protect these assets for expropriation. The information exchanged with the supplier may included the transfer of explicit as well as tacit information between the buyer and the supplier (Stremersch et al. 2003). Tacit information is particularly important for the buyer to protect from misuse, since it may involve skills and experience that may form a basis of the buyer’s competitiveness (Simonin 1999). As suppliers expand their customer base, an indirect link to the buyer and access to information passed to the supplier is established. Having less control over the information passed to the supplier, than if the component were vertically integrated, the buyer faces an enhanced risk of expropriation by a supplier’s new customer of assets and information shared with the supplier and a threat to the buyer’s competitiveness (W illiarnson 1991). To decrease the increased hazard of information leakage, the buyer will need to increase the degree of vertical coordination with the supplier and incur an increase in the cost of governing the relationship with the supplier (Williamson 1991). Direct costs to the buyer to curtail information leakage include the implementation of new procedures and policies with the supplier (Pilling et al. 1994), cost of renegotiating purchase agreements, and amending confidentiality agreements (Artz and Brush 2000). An indirect cost to the buyer is loss of future sales by actions taken by the supplier’s new customer acting on the information supplied by the buyer to the supplier (Kim et al. 2006). Information leaking to the supplier’s new customer may include strategies, competitive benchmarking, codified knowledge, and tacit knowledge in skills and 33 routines (Oxley and Sampson 2004; Polanyi 1966). Consider the situation where the supplier produces a highly customized component for the buyer. If the buyer is obligated to supply critical information, such as trade secrets, to the supplier for the engineering and production of the component, then the buyer may lose control over the information. The supplier may be able to expropriate a portion of the buyer’s investment in servicing the new customer. The situation is of particular importance when the specific asset investment by the buyer is substantial. When substantial assets are invested by the buyer, increased vertical coordination with an individual supplier is necessitated when managing a network of suppliers. The prevention of information leakage provided by a contract is limited ex ante (Grossman and Hart 1986) as contingencies not accounted for arise when a supplier adds new customers (Achrol and Gundlach 1999). To prevent potential information leakage to a supplier’s new customer, greater coordination is required to offset ex post opportunism when nontrivial specific assets are invested in the exchange relationship. In buyer-seller exchange relationships, research has shown that organizations use pledges (Anderson and Weitz 1992), joint action (Heide and John 1990), relational norms (Cannon et al. 2000; Heide and John 1992), and vertical integration (Levy 1985; Masten 1984; Masten et al. 1991) to protect against ex post opportunism. This suggests that buyers will increase the degree of vertical coordination as investments in transaction specific assets increase to curtail opportunism, expropriation of these assets, and leakage of proprietary information by the supplier. H 1: As buyer asset specificity increases, vertical coordination with the supplier increases. 34 Buyer Performance Ambiguity. As an independent entity, a supplier is not under the direct control of the buyer, as would be the case if production of the component were vertically integrated. The diminished degree of control over the supplier creates behavioral uncertainty for the buyer. Behavioral uncertainty arises with the supplier due to the potential of opportunistic inclinations on behalf of the supplier (Stinchombe 1985), and combined with the buyer’s managers bounded rationality, creates a performance evaluation problem for the buyer (Williamson 1985; 197 5). Having an alternative customer decreases the supplier’s dependence on the buyer and increases the potential of opportunistic behavior by the supplier (Yamagishi et al. 1988). Bounded rationality of the buyer’s managers limits the ability of the buyer to accurately assess the supplier’s performance, creating performance ambiguity. Performance ambiguity is the difficulty of accurately measuring ex post the exchange partner’s compliance with expected output (Williamson 1985; 1975). Ouchi (1980) argues that output-based measures be supplemented with control mechanisms to control behavioral uncertainty when performance ambiguity increases. To reduce performance ambiguity, the buyer must increase the monitoring of the supplier’s performance to ensure the supplier conforms to the contractual agreement (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Heide and John 1990). Monitoring decreases the information asymmetry between the buyer and the supplier; however, as monitoring the supplier becomes more time consuming transaction costs increase for the buyer. Managing a network of suppliers, it is particularly important for the buyer to monitor suppliers as suppliers add new customers to ensure the obligations to buyer are met by the supplier. The ability of monitoring to serve as a control mechanism is 35 dependent on the availability of information (Stump and Heide 1996), and performance ambiguity increases as the product delivered by the suppliers becomes increasing intangible and complex (Houston and Johnson 2000). For monitoring to be successful, the object of the monitoring needs to visible to the buyer. If the buyer cannot distinguish the performance level of the supplier, then the cost of monitoring increases. With increasing levels of complexity, the ability of the buyer to write complete contracts deteriorates (Grossman and Hart 1986) and performance ambiguity increases. Increased performance ambiguity will require the buyer to pursue active mechanisms of observation to ensure supplier compliance. Under such conditions, buyers have resorted to greater interfirrn coordination (Andersen and Buvik 2001), joint venture formation (Houston and Johnson 2000), and vertical integration (Anderson 1985; Anderson and Schmittlein 1984) as forms of governance to reduce performance ambiguity. Increasing monitoring efforts reduces performance ambiguity and the incentive of the supplier to act opportunistically (Heide and John 1990). Increased monitoring of the supplier increases the buyer’s ability to detect opportunistic behavior and decreases the incentive for the supplier to act opportunistically. This suggests that buyers managing a network of suppliers will increase vertical coordination with suppliers as the performance ambiguity increases. H2: As buyer performance ambiguity increases, vertical coordination with the supplier increases. Buyer Demand Uncertainty. Demand uncertainty combined with bounded rationality creates an adaptation problem for the buyer (Williamson 1991; 1985; 1975). The demand uncertainty facing the buyer includes not only the volatility of the buyer’s market, but also the buyer’s share of the market. Bounded rationality limits the ability of 36 the buyer’s managers to accurately forecast market demand. In a study of automotive manufacturing, Walker and Weber (1984) found that when demand is difficult to accurately forecast, the likelihood of implementing mechanisms of internal control increases. Vertical integration as a means to reduce demand uncertainty is supported in studies by Levy (1985) and Leiblein and Miller (2003). Similarly, in distribution channel research, the buyer’s likelihood of using direct channels (John and Weitz 1988) and backward integration (Lieberman 1991) increases with demand uncertainty. In a network context, the demand uncertainty in the exchange relationship facing the buyer increases with the addition of a new customer by a supplier in the buyer’s supplier network. The addition of a new customer reflects a change in the capacity of the supplier base in the overall industry. The change in supplier base capacity, may signal changes in the demand for the end product and reduce the ability of the buyer to forecast future demand requirements. By adding the supplier, the new customer may be embarking on a strategy to increase its market share, thereby increasing the volatility of the market. Increases in demand uncertainty may cause fluctuations in the buyer’s demand, and by relying on the supplier, the buyer may experience shortages or excess inventory. The buyer will need to negotiate an increased number of contingencies with the supplier ex post (John and Weitz 1988), and renegotiation increases the costs of the exchange by requiring adaptation of existing routines, procedures, and delivery schedules (Heide and John 1990). Failure to adjust the relationship to account for the change in demand uncertainty may result in maladaptation costs since the existing governance structure is no longer optimal (Williamson 1991). Greater fluctuations in future demand 37 will require increased vertical coordination to counter changes in demand uncertainty on behalf of the buyer with the supplier. H3: As buyer demand uncertainty increases, vertical coordination with the supplier increases. Buyer Technological Uncertainty. Technological uncertainty is the inability to accurately forecast the technical requirements (Walker and Weber 1984). In industries where the pace of technological innovation is frequent, investments in specific assets having low salvage value, increase the capital loss in the event of technological obsolescence as innovation supersedes the existing technology (Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt 1986). In industries with high technological uncertainty, manufacturers cannot produce all the potential innovations internally. Integrating vertically insulates firms from the environment, making them slow to adapt to changes (Lawrence and Lorsch 1967; Robertson and Gatignon 1998). The potential for capital losses resulting from shifts in technology suggests that the benefits of reducing transaction costs by vertically integrating may be offset by retaining flexibility to adapt to changes in technology. In a study of alliance formation, Klein, Frazier and Roth (1990) found that organizations preferred the use of alliances in lieu of vertical integration in volatile technical environments. An advantage of a network of suppliers is the buyer is freed fi'om committing investments internally and being dependent on one technology. By purchasing components fiom a network of suppliers, the buyer has access to new technology offered by other suppliers. By using an intermediate form of governance, buyers are able to react to technological changes in a timely manner and achieve early mover advantages (Klein et al. 1990). This decreases the likelihood that the buyer will lose its competitive 38 advantage due to technological obsolescence. This suggests that in technological volatile environments, the buyer will desire the flexibility to use new technology and minimize agreements that tie the buyer to the supplier long-term leading to a decrease in vertical coordination. H4: As buyer technological uncertainty increases, vertical coordination with the supplier decreases. Supplier New Customer Centrality. In the relationship with the current supplier, the performance ambiguity regarding the actions of the supplier is increased after the supplier adds a new customer. The degree of buyer performance ambiguity is dependent on the position the supplier’s new customer occupies in the industry network. A centrally positioned new customer will increase the buyer performance ambiguity for the buyer due to enhanced reputation and status (Podolny 1993) conferred upon the supplier and decreased dependence of the supplier on the buyer (Cook et a1. 1983; Yamagishi et al. 1988). By being centrally located, an organization’s influence is elevated within the network (Boje and Whetten 1981). A central organization’s influence stems from its ability to control the flow of valued resources and mobilize resources controlled by others (Raub and Weesie 1990). In research of the Japanese automotive industry, Dyer (1997) found that manufacturers exerted influence over their network of suppliers by extensive interfirrn knowledge exchange, investments in specialized assets, and financial linkages. Being linked with a new customer of high status and reputation (Podolny 1993), derived from its central location in the industry network, increases the status of the supplier (Heide and John 1992). If the new customer has a reputation of high quality products, the supplier, by virtue of supplying the new customer, increases its status within the industry as a supplier of high quality components. The increased status, conferred on the supplier 39 by the new customer, can create a sense of obligation and reciprocity (Cook and Emerson 197 8) to the new customer at the expense of the buyer. Changes in behavior could result in the supplier filling orders for the new customer before the buyer’s orders, assigning greater resources to support the new customer, and decreasing responsiveness to the buyer. In addition, having access to the new customer reduces the dependence of the supplier on the buyer (Cook et al. 1983; Yamagishi et al. 1988). The addition of the new customer creates a situation where the new customer and the buyer compete for the supplier’s resources. By Virtue of being between each customer, the supplier is in a position of mediating both relationships by withholding or distorting information given to each customer (Cook and Emerson 1978; Yamagishi et al. 1988). This gives the supplier leverage in negotiations with each customer by playing off each customer to gain favorable terms. Having a new customer increases the potential of the supplier failing to comply with the contract with the buyer. The enhanced reputation and status and decrease in dependence upon the buyer, suggests that the buyer performance ambiguity will be greater if the supplier’s new customer occupies a central location within the industry network. H5: As the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network increases, buyer performance ambiguity increases. Organizations central in an industry network have more access to information, greater influence on other organizations (Freeman 1979; Gnyawali and Madhavan 2001), and are more innovative (Hansen 1999) than non-central organizations. When a supplier in a buyer’s supplier network adds a centrally positioned new customer, future buyer 40 demand uncertainty is increased due to the potential of new innovative products being introduced to the market by the supplier’s new customer. A supplier’s new customer that is centrally located in the industry network will have a greater number of direct linkages and independent access to other organizations than less centrally located organizations (Rindfleisch and Moorrnan 2001). With a greater number of linkages, a centrally positioned new customer is more active in the industry network, forming multiple partnerships with suppliers and collaborative ventures (Baker 1990; Granovetter 1985). Direct linkages supply information that is reliable and timely from trustworthy partners (Becker 1970). Having a greater number of linkages with other organizations, a centrally located new customer is less likely to miss valuable information (Powell et al. 1996) and has access to new information earlier than non-central members of the network (Freeman 1979) Having independent access to other organizations, a centrally located new customer can access information quickly and avoid the control of other organizations (Burt 1992b). Independent access provides the new customer with access to unique and novel information within the industry network (Ahuja 2000; Shan et al. 1994; Valente 1995; Van de Ven 1986). Having multiple information sources, provides multiple avenues for information, which allows a centrally positioned new customer to combine information from diverse sources to generate innovation (Powell et al. 1996). Research in the biotechnology industry found that central organizations had a greater number of collaborative ventures and grew at a greater rate than non-central organizations (Akerlof 1970). Greater independent access to information suggests a supplier’s new customer 41 that is centrally located within an industry network will have an enhanced ability to innovate and introduce new products to the market. With a greater potential to introduce new products to the market than non-central organizations, a centrally located new customer increases buyer demand uncertainty. The buyer will be unsure of the reasons for the new customer establishing a relationship with the supplier. By working with the supplier, the new customer may be signaling a change in its marketing strategy. The new customer may potentially be embarking on a campaign to increase its market share, leading to a potential decrease in the buyer’s market share. On the other hand, the new customer may be switching suppliers to correct a quality problem with an existing supplier, suggesting a potential increase in market share for the buyer. In either case, the addition by the supplier of centrally positioned new customer diminishes the ability of the buyer to accurately forecast future demand greater than if the supplier’s new customer is non-central in the industry network. H6: As the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network increases, buyer demand uncertainty increases. Supplier New Customer Centrality (Moderator). The addition of a new customer by the supplier creates competition for the supplier’s resources between the new customer and the buyer (Cook and Emerson 1978; Yamagishi et a1. 1988). The supplier is in a position to decide which resources to allot in supporting either the new customer or buyer. A centrally located new customer has an enhanced reputation and status within the industry network (Podolny 1993; Raub and Weesie 1990). To enhance its own status, the supplier may be inclined to increase collaboration with the new customer at the expense of the buyer (Burt 1992a). Sensing a change in commitment, the buyer may perceive a heightened potential of opportunistic behavior by the supplier. In addition, a 42 centrally located new customer has greater access to information and resources (Valente 1995) and is more innovative (Hansen 1999). Being able to access information through a network of organizations, a centrally positioned new customer will have developed mature routines and procedures for acquiring and disseminating information (Podolny 1994; Podolny 1993). The mature information processing routines of a central new customer suggests that it will be able to acquire a greater amount of information about the buyer through the supplier than a non-central new customer. The addition of a centrally positioned new customer by the supplier increases the cost of safeguarding the transaction specific assets invested with the supplier. If the new customer is centrally positioned with mature routines for gathering information, then the threat of information passing to the new customer is heightened. To safeguard the assets invested with the supplier, the buyer has three options. First, the buyer may select market governance by bidding the contract to other suppliers capable of making the component. Second, the buyer may choose to continue purchasing from the current supplier and increase the level of vertical coordination with the supplier. Third, the buyer may select to vertically integrate the production of component. Williamson (1985; 1975) postulates that as transaction specific assets increase the cost of safeguarding these assets increases and the buyer would vertically integrate the production of the component. However, when a buyer has outsourced the production of components to a network of suppliers and views the network as an extension of the buyer’s organization, vertical integration is less likely to be the first option considered when substantial assets have been invested with the supplier. By vertically integrating, the buyer must absorb the entire cost of producing the component, whereas switching suppliers allows the buyer to transfer the cost of 43 producing the component to a new supplier and reduces the cost of safeguarding the assets than if the buyer had remained with the current supplier. This suggests that buyers will switch suppliers to protect against the loss of information and expropriation of assets than continue purchasing from the current supplier when the new customer is central to the industry network. H731: Under high centrality of supplier’s new customer in the industry network, buyer asset specificity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of market governance. Alternatively, a new customer that is not central to the industry network is perceived as less of a threat to the buyer’s competitive position. Non-central customers are less likely to have well developed procedures and routines for gathering and disseminating information as compared to central organizations. Thus, it is less likely that non-central customers will be able to gather information from the supplier and use the information to diminish the buyer’s competitive position in the industry. Since the non-central new customer is less of threat to the buyer, the cost of implementing safeguarding procedures with the current customer are less than switching to a new supplier and incurring the cost of qualifying a new supplier, or vertically integrating the production of the component. Thus, when a non-central new customer is added by the current supplier, the buyer is more likely to choose to continue purchasing from the current supplier. H7212: Under low centrality of supplier’s new customer in the industry network, buyer asset specificity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of vertical coordination with the current supplier. 44 If the buyer chooses to continue purchasing from the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then transaction cost economics would recommend the buyer increase the level of vertical coordination with the supplier to safeguard the assets invested. Centrally positioned new customers present a greater threat to the buyer due to enhanced information gathering and dissemination routines (Podolny 1994; Podolny 1993). Safeguarding against the increased potential of opportunistic behavior by the supplier and information leaking to the new customer, increases the likelihood that the buyer will implement greater forms of vertical coordination (Heide and John 1992; Kale et al. 2000). H7b: As the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network increases, the relationship between buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination with the supplier increases. Buyer Supplier Network Density. Density measures the relative number of ties in the network that link organizations together (Galaskiewicz and Wasserman 1989; Walker et al. 1997). Dense buyer-supplier networks facilitate efficient communication and development of shared behavioral expectations amongst members (Coleman 1990; Valente 1995), and can provide information to offset the increased uncertainty due to the addition of a new customer by the supplier. In sparse buyer supplier networks, the amount of information and shared behavioral expectations are lessened. The buyer can reduce the uncertainty with the current supplier by adjusting the governance with the supplier, and the buyer may choose to purchase the component from another supplier by choosing market governance when its supplier network is sparse. In sparse buyer supplier networks, the lack of information availability lessens the buyer’s ability to detect opportunistic behavior, and the buyer can reduce the potential of opportunistic behavior 45 of the current supplier concerning transaction specific assets by switching to another supplier. This suggests that in sparse buyer supplier networks, the propensity of the buyer to opt for market governance will increase after the addition of a new customer by a supplier. H3 a1: Under low buyer supplier network density, buyer asset Specificity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of market governance. Alternatively, in dense buyer supplier networks, shared behavioral expectations and information flowing through the network reduce the prospect of the supplier engaging in opportunistic behavior. Information obtained through a dense network comes at a minimal cost to the buyer, limiting the need of buyer to invest in monitoring of the supplier directly. The ability to access this information lowers the cost of continuing to purchase from the current supplier and diminishes the need to switch suppliers or vertically integrate the production of the component. H332: Under high buyer supplier network density, buyer asset specificity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of vertical coordination with the current supplier. The combination of efficient communication of shared behavioral expectations in dense buyer supplier networks serves to provide the buyer with a mechanism to curtail opportunistic behavior. Since dense networks are efficient means of communicating, information about supplier opportunistic behavior diffuses rapidly through the network to the buyer (Williamson 1991), and the buyer can coordinate pressure on the supplier to conform to expectations (Burt 2000; Coleman 1988; Granovetter 1985) through the use of a coalition of other network members (Coleman 1988; Rowley et al. 2000; Walker et al. 1997). Sanctions carry the threat of reputation loss (Powell and Smith-Doerr 1994), 46 limiting the future prospect of supplying other organizations within the network. The density of the buyer’s supplier network allows the buyer to monitor the actions of the supplier and the new customer efficiently and at a cost less than having to integrate the activity performed by the supplier to protect its investment in specific assets and prevent leakage of information to the supplier’s new customer. Since a dense buyer supplier network decreases the cost of monitoring for the buyer, it is expected that the buyer’s preference for vertical coordination with the supplier will be decreased. Hgb: As buyer supplier network density decreases, the relationship between buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination with the supplier increases. Dense buyer supplier networks also facilitate the diffusion of norms within the network, serving as a constraint on the supplier’s behavior. Firms in the same network imitate one another’s behavior in an attempt to be perceived as legitimate (Galaskiewicz and Wasserman 1989; Walker et al. 1997), and behaviors within the network become similar as shared behavioral expectations are established (Rowley 1997). In sparse buyer supplier networks norms are not well developed. Thus, behavioral expectations are lower and buyer performance ambiguity is increased. When a supplier adds a new customer in a sparse buyer supplier network, the difficulty of monitoring the supplier increases and the supplier conforming to expected behavior is diminished. This suggests that buyers will opt for market governance in sparse buyer supplier networks to offset the increased performance ambiguity after the supplier adds a new customer. H931: Under low buyer supplier network density, buyer performance ambiguity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of market governance. 47 Alternatively, in dense buyer supplier networks, the diffusion of norms serving as a constraint on the supplier’s behavior decreases buyer performance ambiguity. Well developed norms within the buyer supplier network decrease buyer performance ambiguity due to conforming to expectations of behavior established within the network (Heide and John 1992). Failure to adhere to network norms may lead to diminished future opportunities fi'om the buyer and other members of the network. In dense networks, the cost of monitoring a supplier is reduced and the buyer is more likely to continue purchasing from the current supplier instead of switching supplier or producing the component internally. H9212: Under high buyer supplier network density, buyer performance ambiguity (high/low) leads to a governance choice of vertical coordination with the current supplier. In a dense buyer supplier network, information on deviant behavior quickly disseminates to other network members and is sanctioned by other members of the network (Powell and Smith-Doerr 1994). The predictability of behavior in dense networks constrains the behavior of the supplier and promotes cooperation with the buyer. When the density of the buyer supplier network is low, the interconnectivity between suppliers is reduced and developing norms regarding cooperation are difficult to develop and information regarding the supplier’s behavior travels more slowly through the network. Raub and Weesie (1990) demonstrate, using a Prisoner’s Dilemma fi'amework, that organizations in a dense network are constrained from deviant behavior and are more cooperative than organizations in networks where the density is low. Without access to information and the ability to sanction the supplier, the buyer must 48 resort to monitoring the supplier directly. Having access to information and the ability to sanction deviant behavior in a dense supplier network, suggests the buyer’s costs to monitor the supplier are reduced and the need to increase vertical coordination is diminished. Hgb: As buyer supplier network density decreases, the relationship between buyer performance ambiguity and vertical coordination with the supplier increases. The density of a buyer’s supplier network serves as a source of information to reduce uncertainty, both demand and technological, when a supplier adds a new customer. The availability of information is dependent on the density of the buyer supplier network (Coleman 1990; Valente 1995). In dense buyer supplier networks, information is quickly disseminated throughout the buyer’s supplier network. By gathering information from a dense network of suppliers, the buyer can reduce the cost of governing the relationship with the supplier adding the new customer. In contrast, a sparse buyer supplier network fails to provide information necessary to reduce the governance cost of the managing the relationship with the supplier adding the new customer. If a buyer has a sparse network of suppliers, the cost of reducing uncertainty can be lower by opting for market governance and switching to a new supplier where the uncertainty in the new relationship is lower than with the current supplier. This suggests that in sparse buyer supplier networks, the lack of information availability will increase the buyer’s preference for market governance and the buyer will switch to a new supplier to decrease demand and technological uncertainty when a supplier adds a new customer. H1031: Under low buyer supplier network density, buyer demand uncertainty (high/low) leads to a governance choice of market governance. 49 H11a1: Under low buyer supplier network density, buyer technological uncertainty (high/low) leads to a governance choice of market governance. Alternatively, in dense buyer supplier networks, information is available fiom suppliers within the buyer’s supplier network. By accessing this information, a buyer may reduce demand and technological uncertainty created when a supplier adds a new customer. The cost to access this information is minimal to the buyer and reduces the cost of managing the relationship with the current supplier. Having reduced demand uncertainty, the buyer will not need to coordinate changes in production as often. In addition, by accessing information through the network, the buyer will be aware of pending technological changes and can adjust its product offering to account for the changes in technology. This suggests that when buyers have dense supplier networks, they will be less likely to switch suppliers or vertically integrate the production of the component. H1032: Under high buyer supplier network density, buyer demand uncertainty (hi gh/low) leads to a governance choice of vertical coordination with the current supplier. H1132: Under high buyer supplier network density, buyer technological uncertainty (high/low) leads to a governance choice of vertical coordination with the current supplier. If the buyer chooses to continue working with a supplier after the supplier adds a new customer, the density of the buyer’s supplier network influences the level of vertical coordination. As a source of information, the network the can reduce buyer demand uncertainty in its relationship with the supplier. Information supplied by the network is inexpensive, relative to formal governance mechanisms, and is from organizations that the buyer has worked with in the past. Information gathered fi'om these close associates 50 tends to be more reliable and detailed (Granovetter 1985). Research supports the notion that organizations use networks to assess threats and opportunities within the market (Rowley et al. 2000; Walker et al. 1997). In the case of demand uncertainty, the buyer can determine fi'om its network of suppliers if the new customer is adding capacity to embark on a market expansion campaign, thus threatening the buyer’s future market share. On the other hand, the supplier’s new customer may be adding the buyer’s current supplier to address a quality issue with its supplier and the buyer may be able to capitalize on the opportunity to increase its market Share. However, in sparse buyer supplier networks, information regarding the inclinations of the new customer is diminished. This suggests when buyers have a sparse network of suppliers, buyers will need to increase the level of vertical coordination with the supplier adding the new customer to offset demand uncertainty. H101): As buyer supplier network density decreases, the relationship between buyer demand uncertainty and vertical coordination with the supplier increases. Technological uncertainty reduces the ability of the buyer to accurately forecast technical requirements (Walker and Weber 1984). A dense network of suppliers reduces the degree of technological uncertainty confronting the buyer by providing information on technical advances (Valente 1995). The buyer can use this information from its supplier network to determine if the new customer is offering new technology and threatening the buyer’s technology. Conversely, if the buyer supplier network density is low, the flow of information through the network is diminished and the buyer is at a greater threat of technological obsolescence. In sparse buyer supplier networks, the buyer will need to invest in a greater level of vertical coordination directly with the 51 supplier to reduce technological uncertainty. On the other hand, having access to a dense network of suppliers, the buyer can gather timely and reliable information without instituting increased levels of governance with the current supplier. It is expected that if the buyer has a dense network of suppliers, the buyer’s preference for increasing vertical coordination with the supplier will be diminished. H1 1b: As buyer supplier network density decreases, the relationship between buyer technological uncertainty and vertical coordination with the supplier increases. 52 CHAPTER FOUR RESEARCH METHOD The research hypotheses presented in the preceding chapter are empirically tested by examining decisions of supply chain management professionals to adapt existing supplier relationships to accommodate the addition of a new customer by a current supplier in their supplier network. The research of adaptation of supplier relationships poses significant challenges in isolating the phenomenon. Relationships with suppliers typically incorporate a time horizon making immediate adaptation of the relationship difficult. Retrospective surveys require the informant to construct responses for two incidences in time: the time of the addition of the supplier’s new customer and the response at a later date when the purchase agreement is amended. The difference in time between the events introduces confounding factors, limiting the validity of the results (Cook and Campbell 1979). To isolate the factors influencing the decision making process, an experimental scenario design is utilized (e.g., Achrol and Gundlach 1999; Dutta and John 1995; Joshi and Arnold 1997; Pilling et al. 1994). The research for this dissertation is conducted in two phases. In the first phase, a qualitative analysis, literature review, and pre-test are conducted to gain a deeper understanding of the phenomenon. In the qualitative analysis adaptive responses are investigated by interviewing supply chain management professionals and performing a literature review to develop the experimental scenarios. This is followed by the pre-test of potential items to be used in the second phase of the research. The second phase uses role-playing scenarios in seven 2 x 2 mixed design experiments. The transaction cost economic variables (buyer asset specify, buyer performance ambiguity, buyer demand 53 uncertainty, and buyer technological uncertainty) are tested with between group treatments and the network variables (centrality and density) are tested with within group treatments. Validation of Variable Measures and Pre-test Validation of the variable measures and experimental scenarios to be used in this research necessitate a pre-test strategy to specify the domain, purify measures, and establish external validity of the experimental design. The pre-test portion of this research investigates the adaptive responses taken by supply chain management professionals and the validation of the experimental scenarios to be used in the study. The research follows an iterative process to increase the understanding of how the conceptual elements are perceived in industry and how scenarios developed are understood by professionals. The development of the variable measures and experimental scenarios uses a three—step process. The first step focuses on collecting adaptive responses from supply chain management professionals when confronted with the unanticipated addition of a new customer by a supplier. Second, a literature review to compile a list of adaptive responses and potential items for the constructs tested in the experimental design is undertaken. Finally, a pre-test is conducted with supply chain management professionals for each of the items to be used in the experiments. After each step in the process, wording of items and scenarios are altered as needed. The first step entails collecting responses of adaptive behavior taken by supply chain management professionals upon learning of a supplier selling to a new customer using an open-ended question format. The event of learning of a supplier selling to a new customer is conceptualized as an unanticipated event that is new information to the 54 manager (Williamson 1991). A clinical professor of purchasing management assisted in the development of a sampling frame. Forty six supply chain management professionals were contacted by e-mail requesting their participation (Appendix 1) with an outline of the research (Appendix 2). A second e-mail was sent requesting their participation (Appendix 3). After two weeks, a third e-mail was sent as a reminder to non-respondents (Appendix 4). Twenty seven professionals agreed to participant, resulting in a 59% response rate. The twenty seven supply chain professionals were interviewed over the phone using an open-ended question format (Appendix 5) to understand their reaction to supplier adding a new customer. Questions focused on how the subjects would structure relationships with suppliers concerning asset specificity, performance ambiguity, demand uncertainty, and technological uncertainty and how centrality of the supplier’s new customer and the density of their supply network would influence their response concerning the supplier adding the new customer. These professionals stressed the need to reduce uncertainty regarding the relationship with the supplier and avoid any potential adverse effects regarding delivery performance, supplier production capacity, diversion of dedicated resources, and leakage of propriety information. Furthermore, if the supplier’s new customer occupied a central position in the industry, then uncertainty of the relationship with the supplier increased. Professionals with greater experience in supply chain management stressed that the density of their supplier network factored into the decision making process of governing the relationship with individual suppliers. Dense networks served as a source of informal information that reduced the need for an 55 increase in vertical coordination with an individual supplier and reduced the likelihood of switching to a new supplier in the event of a customer being added. The second step consists of conducting a review of the extant literature for measurement scales for vertical coordination and the independent variables. The results of the literature review are presented in Appendix 6. The literature review determined the construct definition (measure) and the items used to measure the construct in previous research. Vertical coordination has been defined as the extent parties carry out focal activities in a cooperative and coordinated way (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik 2000), interfirrn flows of activities, resources, and information in order to coordinate productive values and deal with the realignment of terms of trade (Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000), the regular pattern of similar or complementary actions and activities (J ap 2001), and the purposive organization of the flow of activities and information between the transacting parties (Buvik and John 2000). These definitions of vertical coordination focus on the need for transacting parties to engage in purposive and coordinated action in the exchange of information in pursuit of economic gain. Items used to measure vertical coordination include cooperation with the supplier in quality assurance (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik 2000; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000), resolution of conflicts (Buvik and Gronhaug 2000), price development and market conditions (Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000), new product development (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000), production capacity (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Andersen 2002), and goal setting and forecasting (Artz and Brush 2000). 56 Research focusing on transaction specific assets has defined transaction specific assets as investments made by the OEM/buyer with a particular supplier (Bensaou and Anderson 1999; Buvik 2000; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Reve 2001; Heide 2003; Heide and John 1990; Heide and John 1992; Heide and Stump 1995; Rokkan et al. 2003; Stump 1995; Stump and Heide 1996) and assets invested in export channels (Klein 1989; Skarmeas et al. 2002). Definitions of transaction specific assets stress the idiosyncratic nature of the assets with a particular supplier and the loss of value if these assets are transferred to other uses. Items measuring transaction specific assets account for investments in tooling and equipment (Artz and Brush 2000; Buvik 2000; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Reve 2001; Heide 2003; Heide and John 1990; Heide and John 1992; Heide and Stump 1995; Rokkan et al. 2003; Stump 1995; Stump and Heide 1996), tailoring of the buyer’s production system (Buvik and John 2000; Heide 2003; Jap 2001), training of personnel (Rokkan et al. 2003; Skarmeas et al. 2002), and adaptation of technological standards (Buvik 2000; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Reve 2001; Heide and John 1990; Heide and John 1992; Joshi and Stump 1999). These items address the spectrum of asset specificity to include site specificity, physical asset specificity, human asset specificity, and dedicated assets (Williamson 1985) with a particular supplier in an exchange relationship. Previous research regarding performance ambiguity on part of the buyer has been adapted to the context of the research. For instance, in buyer-supplier relationships, performance ambiguity has been defined as the predictability/difficulty of the buyer in evaluating behavior/performance of the supplier (Heide and John 1990; Heide and Miner 1992; Heide and Stump 1995; Joshi and Stump 1999; Stump and Heide 1996). In a 57 franchisor/franchisee context, Antia and Frazier (2001) define performance ambiguity as the “extent of information available regarding agent performance,” and in a manufacturer/distributor context, performance ambiguity is defined as the “ex ante difficulty faced by the manufacturer in evaluating the specific geographic area covered by the distributor” (Bergen et al. 1998). Items used to measure performance ambiguity in buyer-supplier relationships include ability to predict prices from the supplier (Heide and John 1990; Heide and Miner 1992; Joshi and Stump 1999), ability to predict delivery performance (Heide and Stump 1995; Joshi and Stump 1999), ability of supplier to adapt to changes in order specifications (Heide and Stump 1995; Joshi and Stump 1999), and monitoring of supplier (Heide and John 1990; Heide and Miner 1992). Prior research has separated environmental uncertainty into demand uncertainty and technological uncertainty. Demand uncertainty has been defined as changing market conditions (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000), price and volume uncertainty (Artz and Brush 2000), and inability to forecast volume requirements (Bensaou and Anderson 1999; Heide and John 1990; Heide and Stump 1995; Robertson and Gatignon 1998). Items used to measure demand uncertainty include demand for end product varies continually (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Artz and Brush 2000; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000), volume requirements for this component are predictable/reliable (Bensaou and Anderson 1999), demand is difficult to forecast (Robertson and Gatignon 1998), and predictability of industry sales volume for end product (Ganesan 1994; Heide and John 1990; Heide and Stump 1995). These items capture both the inability to predict the future demand for the end product and the 58 inability to provide the supplier with accurate volume predictions needed for production scheduling. Technological uncertainty has been defined in prior research as technological dynamism (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000), likelihood of major changes in a component, performance, and manufacturing processes (Bensaou and Anderson 1999), extent of technical innovation and rate of change of technology (Celly et al. 1999), inability to predict accurately technological changes in product and/or process technology (Robertson and Gatignon 1998; Stump 1995; Stump and Heide 1996), and inability to forecast accurately the technological requirements in a relationship (Heide and John 1990). Items used to measure technological uncertainty include product purchased has high innovation rates and short life cycles (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000; Robertson and Gatignon 1998), predictability of technological changes in the end product (Stump and Heide 1996), and changes in product specifications (Heide and John 1990; Stump 1995; Walker and Weber 1984). These definitions and items conceptualize technological uncertainty as external to the focal buyer-supplier relationship that influence the predictability of technical changes to the end product or components purchased and the inability to forecast technical specifications for the supplier on behalf of the buyer. Empirical research regarding the network variables centrality and density in supply chain literature is limited to research conduced by Antia and Frazier (2001). Centrality is defined as the strength of an individual agent’s position in an agent network. Items to measure the agent’s position are crucial cog in the franchisee network, maintain few relations in other franchisees, activity in franchise network, number of links with 59 other franchisees, and centrality in franchise system. Density is defined as the average strength of relations in a network. Items to measure the density of a network are franchisees share close ties amongst themselves, degree of interaction among franchisees, closeness of relations among franchisees, degree of communication and discussion of common problems among franchisees, and cohesiveness. This research investigates the adaptation of governance in an existing buyer- supplier dyad when an unanticipated event occurs, specifically when the supplier adds a new customer. As the scales in the extant literature were meant for different contexts, the scales are adapted to the context and focus of this study where necessary, based on the responses of the supply chain management professionals interviewed in step one and input from academic experts familiar with transaction cost economics and network theory. In the third step, a pre-test of the items used in each of the scenarios is conducted with eighteen professionals. The questionnaire e-mailed to each professional is presented in Appendix 7. In the pre-test, each of the items is tested individually for its effect on vertical coordination. Consistent with transaction cost economics, the high treatments for buyer asset specificity, performance ambiguity, demand uncertainty, and technological uncertainty led to increased vertical coordination with the supplier (p < .001). Testing of the control variables showed that market position had no effect on vertical coordination; however, having a single supplier (p < .001), few qualified suppliers in the market (p < .001), and purchasing frequency (p < .01) led to increased vertical coordination with the supplier. The results for the transaction cost and control variables are presented in Table 4. The results for buyer supplier network density and supplier new customer centrality 60 are presented in Table 5 and were not significantly different between the high and low treatments. However, all four treatments were significantly different than zero, indicating that the subjects were adapting the governance and increasing the degree of vertical coordination with the supplier due to the addition of the new customer. After completing the survey, each participant was interviewed to assess how well each item was comprehended and measured the intended construct. Analysis of the results revealed that the manipulations were directionally correct and were well understood by the participants. Suggestions for improvement of the wording were incorporated in to the scenarios used in the seven role-playing experiments. Experiment Method and Design Sampling Frame. A key informant methodology is used to generate the data for this research. The sampling fi'ame chosen for this research requires knowledgeable professionals as key informants (Campbell 1955; John and Reve 1982). Subjects for this research required supply chain management professionals that possess unique knowledge required in the adaptation of purchasing agreements and management of supplier relationships. Supply chain management professionals have responsibility for developing, negotiating, managing, and monitoring supplier contract performance (Cannon et al. 2000). The sampling frame consists of supply chain professionals who are members of the Institute for Supply Management (ISM)3. A subset of 4630 ISM supply chain management professionals from Standard Industry Codes (SIC) 350, 360, 370, and 3 Formerly known as the National Association of Purchasing Management 61 3804 were randomly selected. Members supplying a home address were removed and only professionals supplying a work address in the US. were included in the sample. A final sample of 2681 resulted. Phone numbers for the sample were obtained from whitepages.com and Verizon information. Response Rate. For the seven role-playing experiments 867 supply chain management professionals were contacted, 504 agreed to participate and 363 either declined to participate (123), no longer worked for the firm (178), or the phone number was unavailable for the firm (62), leading to a response rate of 58%. Of the supply chain management professionals that agreed to participate, 336 are male and 168 are female, and 257 of the respondents are managers and 247 are non-managers. Of the supply chain management professionals that did not participate, 216 are male and 147 are female, and 160 of the respondents are managers and 187 are non-managers. Sample Characteristics. The sample consists of 504 supply chain management professionals. The characteristics of the respondents are presented in Table 6. The sample comprises 336 males and 168 females. Segmented by industry, 190 respondents are fi'om SIC 350, 118 respondents are from SIC 360, 107 respondents are from SIC 370, and 89 respondents are from SIC 380. Respondents from firms of less than 500 employees amounted to 153, and 351 respondents are from firms with greater than 500 employees. Segmented by job title, 253 of the respondents are managers and 251 are non-managers. Unit of Analysis. Consistent with transaction cost economics, the unit of analysis for this research is the exchange relationship (Williamson 1985; 1975). This research 4 Corresponds to North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) codes 333, 334, 335, 336, and 339 62 focuses on the adaptation of the exchange relationship from the buyer’s perspective. The focal exchange relationship for this research is the relationship between a buyer and its supplier established before the addition of a new customer by the supplier. The conceptualization of the need to adapt the exchange relationship arises from the addition of a new customer by the supplier. The addition of the new customer introduces an external disturbance to the relationship between the buyer and the supplier which needs to be accounted for to prevent maladaptation costs (Williamson 1991). Design and Procedure. Seven individual role-playing scenarios using a 2 x 2 mixed design experiment were conducted to test the model. Subjects were presented a role-playing scenario where they were to imagine themselves in a given treatment condition. Role-playing scenarios provide controlled study of behavior where subjects enact the scenario described (Geller 1978) and can be an appropriate research method to capture the decision making process of subjects (Forward et al. 1976). The use of role- playing experiments has been shown to be an effective approach for operationalizing variables in a supply chain context (Achrol and Gundlach 1999; Dutta and John 1995; Jackson Jr. et a1. 1984; Joshi and Arnold 1997; Pilling et al. 1994; Wuyts et al. 2004). In each experiment, the transaction cost variable (buyer asset specificity, buyer performance ambiguity, buyer demand uncertainty, and buyer technological uncertainty) is tested between groups, and the network variable (centrality and density) is tested within groups. Scenarios for each treatment are presented in Appendix 8 to 21. Each treatment consists of 36 randomly assigned subjects. To control for order effect, in each of the seven experiments, the subjects are divided into two groups of 18 subjects each. For one group, the high treatment for the Within group variable (centrality or density) is presented first. 63 For second group, the low treatment for the within group variable (centrality or density) is presented first. The scenario was developed for the subjects to role-play the position of a supply chain manager responsible for acquiring CD-ROM drives for a leading computer manufacturer. The choice of CD-ROM drives was made based on the subjects’ familiarity of CD-ROMS drives, the need to exchange technical and marketing information to integrate the CD—ROM drive with the computer, and the market maturity for CD-ROM drives. The purchase of CD-ROM drives requires the subject to weigh the decision to continue working with the current supplier while retaining the option to switch to another supplier. Acquiring the CD-ROM drive requires the buyer to share sensitive technical and marketing information with the supplier, exposing the buyer to opportunistic behavior on behalf of the supplier (Williamson 1985; 1975). In contrast, the buyer may protect against opportunistic behavior by developing norms and familiarity with the supplier (Heide and John 1992; Noordewier et al. 1990) through repetitive purchases over a period of time and retaining the option to exit the relationship and purchase the CD-ROM drives from other suppliers in a mature market. Each treatment was administered over the phone. Presentation of the scenario and collection of data took approximately five minutes for each treatment. For each scenario, each subject was instructed to assume a role-playing posture in which they assumed the position of supply chain manager responsible for buying CD-ROM drives for a leading computer manufacturer. For each subject, vertical coordination was defined followed by presentation of the assigned scenario. In the mixed design experiment, each subject was first presented their assigned treatment regarding the transaction cost economics variable 64 of interest and asked the degree of coordination they would recommend with the supplier on a 7-point scale (1 = very limited coordination, 7 = very extensive coordination). The subjects were then informed that the supplier had unexpectedly added a new customer that had previously not worked with any suppliers in their network. This was followed by administering a within subject treatment of the network variable (centrality or density). After each treatment, subjects were instructed to recommend one of three choices of action (find another supplier, produce internally, or continue purchasing from the current supplier). If a subject recommended to continue purchasing from the current supplier, then they were instructed to recommend the level of coordination they would have with the supplier after the addition of the new customer on a ll-point scale (-5 = extremely decrease, 0 = same level of coordination, 5 = extremely increase). Each scenario was concluded by gathering data on the subjects experience in supply chain management (number of years), position, supplier network size, industry, and firm size (number of employees). Dependent Variable Vertical Coordination. Vertical coordination is conceptualized as the purposive organization of the flow of activities and information between the buyer and the supplier (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000). Vertical coordination is operationalized as the degree of information exchanged between the buyer and the supplier. Information exchanged included production costs, market conditions for the end product, future market strategies, and joint efforts in product development and quality control (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Andersen 2002; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000). 65 Independent Variables Buyer Asset Specificity. Buyer asset specificity is conceptualized as the buyer’s investments that are undertaken in support of a particular transaction, where the salvage value of the investments is much lower in best alternative uses or by alternative users should the original transaction be prematurely terminated (Williamson 1985; 1975). Buyer asset specificity describes the investments made by the buyer in physical assets, production processes, and knowledge that are Specific to the supplier (Buvik and John 2000; Heide and John 1990; Joshi and Stump 1999). Buyer asset specificity is operationalized as the degree of investment by the buyer specifically with the current supplier. The treatment for buyer asset specificity contrasts the degree of investment by the buyer with the current supplier. Buyer asset specificity is manipulated as “You have made significant investments specifically with this supplier” (high buyer asset Specificity) and “You have made few investments specifically with this supplier” (low buyer asset specificity). Buyer Performance Ambiguity. Buyer performance ambiguity is conceptualized as the uncertainty of the buyer to accurately evaluate the supplier’s ex post performance (Heide and John 1990). Buyer performance ambiguity is operationalized as the inability of the buyer to accurately predict supplier performance with regard to price and delivery (J oshi and Stump 1999). Buyer performance ambiguity is manipulated as “You have been unable to accurately measure prices and delivery performance of this supplier easily (high buyer performance ambiguity) and “You have been able to accurately measure prices and delivery performance of this supplier easily (low buyer performance ambiguity). 66 Buyer Demand Uncertainty. Demand uncertainty is conceptualized as the buyer’s inability to accurately forecast the volume requirements (Walker and Weber 1984). Buyer demand uncertainty reflects the changing conditions of the markets that the organization is engaged (Buvik and John 2000), and the buyer’s inability to forecast accurately the demand for the components from the supplier (Heide and John 1990). Buyer demand uncertainty is operationalized as the degree of demand uncertainty facing the buyer due to demand volatility and the ability to forecast production volumes for the supplier (Buvik and John 2000). Buyer demand uncertainty is manipulated as “T he demand for your computers varies continually and it is difi‘icult to forecast production volumes for your supplier” (high buyer demand uncertainty) and “The demand for your computers is steady and it is easy to forecast production volumes for your supplier ” (low buyer demand uncertainty). Buyer Technological Uncertainty. Buyer technological uncertainty is conceptualized as the buyer’s inability to accurately forecast technical requirements (Walker and Weber 1984). Buyer technological uncertainty reflects the frequency of expected changes to the component and future technological improvements to the component (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Buvik and John 2000). Buyer technological uncertainty is operationalized as the degree of technological uncertainty facing the buyer due to technological change and the ability to forecast requirements (Heide and John 1990). Buyer technological uncertainty is manipulated as “Technology changes rapidly and it is difi‘icult to forecast requirements ” (high buyer technological uncertainty) and “Technology changes slowly and it is easy to forecast requirements ” (low buyer technological uncertainty). 67 Supplier New Customer Centrality. Centrality in a network is conceptualized as the organization’s position in the network relative to others (Wasserman and Faust 1994). Network centrality measures the degree to which organizations occupy a position of influence and status within the network (Podolny 1993). Supplier new customer centrality is operationalized as the new customer’s competitive position in the industry network and the number of ties with other organizations in the industry (Antia and Frazier 2001). Supplier new customer network centrality is manipulated as “The supplier ’s new customer is a competitor and maintains many ties with other organizations within the industry” (high supplier new customer network centrality) and “The supplier’s new customer is not a competitor and maintains few ties with other organizations within the industry” (low supplier new customer network centrality). Buyer Supplier Network Density. Buyer supplier network density is conceptualized as the interconnectiveness of organizations within a network (Coleman 198 8). Buyer supplier network density reflects the relative number of links between organizations within the buyer’s supplier network. Buyer supplier network density is operationalized as the cohesiveness of the buyer’s supplier network and interaction amongst the suppliers (Antia and Frazier 2001). Buyer supplier network density is manipulated as “Your network of suppliers is very cohesive with extensive interaction amongst the suppliers” (high buyer supplier network density) and “Your network of suppliers is not very cohesive with no interaction amongst suppliers ” (low buyer supplier network density). 68 Control Variables Purchasing Frequency. Transaction cost economics assumes that purchasing frequency is associated with specialized assets in support of the transaction, and that increased asset specificity increases the exposure to opportunism (Williamson 1985; 1975). To control for purchase frequency, purchase frequency is held constant across the scenarios at a high level (You have been frequently purchasing CD-ROM drives from a single supplier... ). Relationship Duration. As the duration of the relationship increases between two firms, relational norms, trust, and personal relationships evolve between the supplier and buyer, reducing the threat of opportunism and decreasing ex post transaction costs (Bradach and Eccles 1989; Heide and John 1992). To control for relationship duration, relationship duration is held constant across the scenarios at two years (. . .frequently purchasing CD-ROM drives from a single supplier for two years). Industry. The propensity to vertically integrate and supplier network configuration vary between industries (Balakrishnan and Wemerfelt 1986; Bell 2005). To control for differences between industries, the product purchased (CD-ROM drives) and the end product (computer) are held constant across scenarios. In addition, the industry for each subject was collected to investigate the consistency of responses from the subjects across the four industries comprising the sampling frame. Firm Size. Firm size can influence the behavior of the firm (Cyert and March 1992). Research has shown that larger firms have access to greater resources and an ability to overcome the cost of changing the suppliers (Anderson 1985). Larger firms may have greater bargaining power and can negotiate for greater control in their 69 relationships with suppliers (Ganesan 1993). F inn size is controlled for by two methods. First, firm Size is held constant between the scenarios by instructing subjects that they are purchasing components for a leading computer manufacturer (Imagine you are a supply chain manager responsible for acquiring CD-ROM drives for a leading manufacturer of computers). Second, post hoc, using data gathered from each subject, firm size (measured as number of employees) is used to investigate the consistency of responses from subjects for firms with less than 500 employees (coded as 0) and firms with greater than 500 employees (coded as l)5. Gender. The gender of the subjects was collected and coded using a dummy variable. Male subjects are coded as 1, and female subjects are coded as 0. 5 In the United States, the Small Business Administration has traditionally defined small businesses as less than 500 employees. 70 CHAPTER FIVE RESULTS The hypotheses are tested using seven role-playing mixed design experiments. The transaction cost economics variables, buyer asset specificity, buyer performance ambiguity, buyer demand uncertainty, and buyer technological uncertainty, are tested between groups. The network variables, supplier new customer centrality and buyer supplier network density, are tested within groups. Following accepted practice in the marketing discipline, significance of hypothesis testing is found at p-values of 0.05 and 0.1. For each of the experiments where hypotheses were tested in a mixed design, a Bonferroni correction factor is applied to account for the use of the same subjects in testing two hypotheses. A summary of the results is presented in Tables 7 and 8. Transaction Cost E conomics Prescriptions Hypothesis One. Consistent with transaction cost economics, H1 postulates when significant assets are invested by the buyer specifically with the supplier, the buyer will desire greater vertical coordination with the supplier. In support of H1, buyer asset specificity has a significant impact on vertical coordination with the supplier (p < 0.05; Bonferroni Correction Factor p < 0.1), with the buyer desiring greater vertical coordination when the buyer has invested significant assets specifically with the supplier. The Levene statistic indicates that the two groups have homogenous variance (p = 0.995, NS). Analysis of the control variables for industry (F = 0.443, NS), firm size (p = 0.285, 71 NS), and, gender (p = 0.616, NS) indicate no significant effect on buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination. Hypothesis Two. Hypothesis 2 postulates when buyer performance ambiguity increases, the buyer will desire greater vertical coordination with the supplier. In support of H2, buyer performance ambiguity has a significant impact on vertical coordination with the supplier (p < 0.05; Bonferroni Correction Factor p < 0.05), with the buyer desiring greater vertical coordination when buyer performance ambiguity increases. The Levene statistic indicates that the two groups have homogenous variance (p = 0.053, NS). Analysis of the control variables for industry (F = 0.583, NS), firm size (p = 0.918, NS), and gender (p = 0.454, NS) indicate no significant effect on buyer performance ambiguity and vertical coordination. Hypothesis Three. Hypothesis 3 postulates when buyer demand uncertainty increases, the buyer will desire greater vertical coordination with the supplier. In support of H3, as buyer demand uncertainty increases, the buyer desires greater vertical coordination with the supplier (p < 0.05; Bonferroni Correction Factor p < 0.05). The Levene statistic indicates that the two groups do not have homogenous variance (p = 0.021), and analysis of this hypothesis does not assume equal variances between the two groups. Analysis of the control variables for industry (F = 0.861, NS), firm size (p = 0.878, NS), and gender (p = 0.540, NS) indicate no significant effect on buyer demand uncertainty and vertical coordination. Hypothesis Four. Hypothesis 4 postulates when buyer technological uncertainty increases, the buyer will desire less vertical coordination with the supplier. The results indicate that there is not a significant difference between the low and high treatments of 72 technological uncertainty and the buyer’s desire for vertical coordination (p = 0.216, NS). Therefore, H4 is not supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the two groups have homogenous variance (p = 0.735, NS). Analysis of the control variables for industry (F = 0.295, NS), firm size (p = 0.348, NS), and gender (p = 0.366, NS) indicate no significant effect on buyer technological uncertainty and vertical coordination. Supplier New Customer Centrality Hypothesis Five. Hypothesis 5 predicts the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network will be positively related to buyer performance ambiguity. The results indicate that for both high and low buyer performance ambiguity there 5 not a significant difference between the high and low treatments for centrality of the supplier’s new customer. Therefore, H5 is not supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the centrality of the supplier’s new customer for both the high buyer performance ambiguity (p = 0.548, NS) and low buyer performance ambiguity (p = 0.801 , NS) treatments have homogenous variances. An order effect is present in the within group centrality treatment for the high buyer performance ambiguity treatment (Central customer presented first, p = 0.01; Non-central customer presented first, p = 0.02) and low buyer performance ambiguity treatment (N on- central customer presented first, p = 0.035). Analysis of the control variables for each buyer performance ambiguity treatment indicate industry (FLOW = 0.433, NS; FHigh = 0.307, NS), firm size (pLOW = 0.135, NS; pHigh = 0.233, NS), and gender (pHigh = 0.457, NS) have no significant effect on centrality of the supplier’s new customer and buyer performance ambiguity. However, the results for the low buyer performance ambiguity 73 treatment indicate a significant difference in responses due to gender (pLOW = 0.035), with females having greater performance ambiguity when a central customer is added by the supplier. Hypothesis Six. Hypothesis 6 predicts the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network will be positively related to buyer demand uncertainty. The centrality of the supplier’s new customer increases the buyer demand uncertainty for the low treatment for buyer demand uncertainty (p < 0.1), but is not significant for the high treatment of buyer demand uncertainty, providing partial support for H6. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the centrality of the supplier’s new customer for both the high (p = 0.805, NS) buyer demand uncertainty and low (p = 0.249, NS) buyer demand uncertainty treatments have homogenous variances. An order effect is present in the within group centrality treatment for the high buyer demand uncertainty treatment (N on-central customer presented first, p= 0.014), but is not present in the low demand uncertainty treatment within group centrality treatment. Analysis of the control variables for each buyer demand uncertainty treatment indicate industry (F L0 = 0.624, NS; F - = 0.049, NS; Tukey test indicates no difference between W High industries), firm size (pLow = 0.876, NS; pHigh = 0.235, NS), and gender (pLOW = 0.590, NS) have no significant effect on centrality of the supplier’s new customer. However, the results for the high buyer demand uncertainty treatment indicate a significant difference in res onses due to gender (p . = 0.007), with females having greater demand P HIgh uncertainty when a central customer is added by the supplier. 74 Hypothesis Seven. Hypotheses 7a1, 7a2, and 7b test the moderating effect of the centrality of the supplier’s new customer in the industry network on the buyer asset specificity/vertical coordination relationship. Hypothesis 7a1 predicts the buyer will prefer the market governance option and switch to a new supplier instead of producing the component internally or continuing to purchase from the current supplier when the supplier’s new customer occupies a central position in the industry network. In support of H7a1, when the supplier’s new customer is central to the industry network, buyers Significantly Opted for market governance for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer asset specificity. Hypothesis 7a2 predicts the buyer will continue purchasing from the current supplier when the supplier’s new customer is not central to the industry network. In support of H732, when the supplier’s new customer is not central to the industry network, buyers Significantly opted to continue purchasing from the current supplier for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer asset specificity. If the buyer chose to continue purchasing from the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then H71, predicts the centrality of the supplier’s new customer will positively moderate the relationship between buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination. The results indicate that the position the supplier’s new customer in the industry network does not have a significant influence on the degree of vertical coordination desired by the buyer. Therefore, H7b is not supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the centrality of the supplier’s new customer treatment for the high buyer asset specificity treatment have homogenous 75 variances (p = 0.250, NS). However, the Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the centrality of the supplier’s new customer treatment for the low buyer asset specificity treatment do not have homogenous variances (p = 0.032), and analysis of the low buyer asset specificity treatment does not assume equal variances between the two groups. An order effect is not present for the within group centrality treatment for either the high buyer asset specificity or low buyer asset Specificity treatments. Analysis of the control variables for each buyer asset specificity treatment indicate industry (FLOW = 0.067, NS; F = 0.773, NS), firm size (p = 0.588, NS; p . = 0.413, NS), and gender (p Low High Low High = 0.779 NS) have no significant effect on the centrality of the supplier’s new customer within group treatment. However, the results for the high buyer asset specificity treatment indicate a significant difference in responses due to gender (pHigh = 0.003) with females desiring greater vertical coordination when a central customer is added by the supplier. Buyer Supplier Network Density Hypothesis Eight. Hypotheses 8a1, 8a2, and 8b test the moderating effect of buyer supplier network density on the buyer asset specificity/vertical coordination relationship. H8al predicts when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, the buyer will prefer the market governance option and switch to a new supplier instead of producing the component internally or continuing to purchase from the current supplier. In support of H881, when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, buyers 76 Significantly opted for market governance for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer asset specificity. Hypothesis 8a2 predicts the buyer will continue purchasing from the current supplier when the buyer supplier network density is high. In support of Hgaz, when the buyer supplier network density is high, buyers significantly opted to continue purchasing form the current supplier for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer asset Specificity. If the buyer chose to continue purchasing from the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then Hgb predicts the density of the buyer’s supplier network will inversely moderate the relationship between buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination. For both treatments of buyer asset specificity, when the buyer has invested significant assets and when the buyer has invested few assets specifically with the supplier, the density of the buyer’s supplier network does not significantly moderate the relationship between buyer asset specificity and vertical coordination. Therefore, Hgb is not supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the buyer’s supplier network density for both the high buyer asset specificity (p = 0.271, NS) and low buyer asset specificity (p = 0.709, NS) treatments have homogenous variances. An order effect is not present in the within group buyer’s supplier network density treatment for either the high buyer asset specificity or low buyer asset specificity treatments. Analysis of the control variables indicate a difference in responses for the buyer’s supplier network density due to industry (FHigh = 0.022), where respondents fi'om SIC 360 desire greater vertical 77 coordination than respondents from SIC 350. No differences in the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment are detected due to industry (FLow = 0.093, NS), firm size (pHigh = 0.474, NS; pLOW = 0.347, NS), and gender (pHigh = 0.308, NS; pLOW = 0.395, NS). Hypothesis Nine. Hypotheses 9a1, 9a2, and 9b test the moderating effect of buyer supplier network density on the buyer performance ambiguity/vertical coordination relationship. H931 predicts when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, the buyer will prefer the market governance option and switch to a new supplier instead of producing the component internally or continuing to purchase fi'om the current supplier. For both the high and low treatments of buyer performance ambiguity, the results indicate in low density buyer supplier networks, buyers did not significantly opt for market governance. Therefore, H981 is not supported. Hypothesis 9a2 predicts when the buyer’s supplier network density is high, the buyer will continue to purchase from the current supplier. For both the high and low treatments of buyer performance ambiguity, the results indicate buyers did not significantly choose to continue purchasing from the current supplier. Therefore, H9212 is not supported. If the buyer chose to continue purchasing from the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then H91, predicts the density of the buyer’s supplier network will inversely moderate the relationship between buyer performance ambiguity and vertical coordination. For both treatments of buyer performance ambiguity, the 78 density of the buyer’s supplier network does not significantly moderate the relationship between buyer performance ambiguity and vertical coordination. Therefore, H9}, is not supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for buyer’s supplier network density for the high buyer performance ambiguity (p = 0.603, NS) treatment have homogenous variances. The Levene statistic (p = 0.015) indicated that the groups for the low buyer performance ambiguity treatment did not have homogenous variances, and the analysis is conducted assuming not equal variances. An order effect is not present in the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment for either the high buyer performance ambiguity or low buyer performance ambiguity treatments. Analysis of the control variables for industry (FHigh = 0.137, NS; FLow = 0.264, NS), firm size (pHigh = 0.257, NS; pLOW = 0.865, NS), and gender (pHigh = 0.968, NS; pLOW = 0.261, NS) indicate no significant effect on the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment. Hypothesis T en. Hypotheses 10a], 10a2, and 10b test the moderating effect of buyer supplier network density on the buyer demand uncertainty/vertical coordination relationship. H1081 predicts when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, the buyer will prefer the market governance option and switch to a new supplier instead of producing the component internally or continuing to purchase from the current supplier. In support of H1031, when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, buyers significantly opted for market governance for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer demand uncertainty. 79 Hypothesis 10a2 predicts the buyer will continue purchasing from the current supplier when the buyer supplier network density is high. In support of H1032, when the buyer supplier network density is high, buyers significantly opted to continue purchasing form the current supplier for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer demand uncertainty. If the buyer chose to continue purchasing from the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then H101, predicts that the density of the buyer’s supplier network will inversely moderate the relationship between buyer demand uncertainty and vertical coordination. The density of the buyer’s supplier network does not moderate the degree of vertical coordination for the high buyer demand uncertainty treatment; however, the density of the buyer’s supplier network significantly moderates the low buyer demand uncertainty treatment (p < 0.05; Bonferroni Correction Factor p < 0.1), with the buyer desiring greater vertical coordination when buyer supplier network density is low. Therefore, H101, is partially supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the buyer’s supplier network density for both the high buyer demand uncertainty (p = 0.500, NS) and low buyer demand uncertainty (p = 0.118, NS) treatments have homogenous variances. An order effect is present in the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment for the high buyer demand uncertainty treatment (Central customer presented first, p = 0.024), but is not present in the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment for the low demand uncertainty treatment. Analysis of the control variables for industry (FHigh = 0.414, NS; FLOW = 0.677, NS), firm size (pLOW = 0.475, NS), and gender (pHigh = 80 0.766, NS; pLOW =0.190, NS) indicate no significant effect on the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment. However, for the high buyer demand uncertainty treatment, firm size (pHigh = 0.039) indicated a difference in responses between small (< 500 employees) and large (> 500 employees) firms, with smaller firms desiring greater vertical coordination. Hypothesis Eleven. Hypotheses 1 1a1, 11a2 and 11b test the moderating effect of buyer supplier network density on the buyer technological uncertainty/vertical coordination relationship. H1131 predicts when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, the buyer will prefer the market governance option and switch to a new supplier instead of producing the component internally or continuing to purchase from the current supplier. In support of H1 131, when the buyer’s supplier network density is low, buyers significantly opted for market governance for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer technological uncertainty. Hypothesis 11a2 predicts the buyer will continue purchasing from the current supplier when the buyer supplier network density is high. In support of H1132, when the buyer supplier network density is high, buyers significantly opted to continue purchasing form the current supplier for both the high (p < 0.05) and low (p < 0.05) treatments of buyer technological uncertainty. If the buyer chose to continue purchasing fiom the current supplier after the addition of the new customer, then H111, predicts that the density of the buyer’s supplier network will inversely moderate the relationship between buyer technological uncertainty 81 and vertical coordination. The buyer’s supplier network density significantly increases the degree of vertical coordination when buyer technological uncertainty is high (p < 0.1; Bonferroni Correction Factor, NS); however, when buyer technological uncertainty is low the density of the buyer’s supplier network does not significantly moderate the relationship. Therefore, H1 1b is partially supported. The Levene statistic indicates that the groups for the buyer’s supplier network density for both the high buyer technological uncertainty (p = 0.317, NS) and low buyer technological uncertainty (p = 0.729, NS) treatments have homogenous variances. An order effect is not present in the within group density treatment for either the high buyer technological uncertainty or low buyer technological uncertainty treatments. Analysis of the control variables for industry (F = 0.565, NS; Flow = 0.480, NS), firm size High (pHigh = 0.346, NS; pLOW = 0.453, NS) gender (pHigh = 0.130, NS; pLOW = 0.183, NS) indicate no significant effect on the buyer’s supplier network density within group treatment. 82 CHAFI‘ ER SIX THEORETICAL AND MANAGERIAL CONTRIBUTIONS OF THE STUDY The objective of this dissertation was to integrate a network perspective with transaction cost economics. Specifically, this research addressed how a buyer adapts its relationship with a supplier due to structural changes occurring within a network of suppliers. A limitation of transaction cost economics is a failure to account for “interdependencies among a series of related contracts” (Williamson 1985, p. 393) when examining a relationship between a buyer and supplier. Scholars have recently suggested that to fully understand dyadic relationships, a network perspective needs to be incorporated (Antia and Frazier 2001; Geyskens et al. 2006; Wathne and Heide 2004). Using established transaction cost economics logic, this research integrated the structural dimensions of centrality and density from network theory to address the governance of a buyer with a current supplier that has added a new customer. The addition of the new customer introduces uncertainty in the existing dyadic relationship between the buyer and the current supplier due to the change in the surrounding network. As such, this research focuses on the buyer’s adaptation of the dyadic governance and addresses the following two research questions. First, does the centrality in the industry network of the supplier’s new customer influence the governance in an existing relationship? Second, does the density of the buyer’s supplier network moderate the governance with the current supplier when a new relationship is added to the network? The results of this research provide evidence that dyadic relationships are influenced by the network in which they exist, and a deeper understanding of adaptive governance is gained when a network perspective is integrated with transaction cost economics logic. 83 Theoretical Contributions Four conclusions are drawn from the results of this research. First, the transaction cost economics prescriptions of increased transaction asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty, and demand uncertainty in a buyer-supplier dyadic relationship lead to increased vertical coordination with a supplier are supported6, providing nomological support and internal consistency of the model. Second, the centrality in the industry network of supplier’s new customer increases the future buyer demand uncertainty when demand uncertainty is initially low and moderates the dyadic governance concerning buyer asset specificity. Third, the buyer’s supplier network density moderates vertical coordination with the supplier when buyer demand uncertainty is initially low and buyer teChnological uncertainty initially high. Finally, buyer supplier network density has a Significant influence on governance choice. In low density buyer supplier networks, buyers opted for market governance, and in high density buyer supplier networks, buyers Choose to continue purchasing form the current supplier when a new customer is added by the supplier. Transaction Cost Economics Prescriptions. Transaction cost economics prescribes three forms of governance (market, hybrid, and vertical integration) in managing marketing channels (Heide 1994; Williamson 1985; 1975). Manufacturing fil‘rns purchase components from a network of suppliers engage in a form of hybrid governance, where the cost to manage the relationship is greater than market governance and lower than producing the component internally (Williamson 1991), where the cost of governance is driven by the degree of asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty, and \ Increased technological uncertainty leading to greater vertical coordination with the supplier was not Supported. 84 environmental (demand and technological) uncertainty. In hybrid governance, as these dimensions increase, vertical coordination between the buyer and a supplier escalates (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Combs and Ketchen 1999) and the level of joint action increases (Heide and John 1990; J oshi and Stump 1999). Consistent with transaction cost economics, the results of this research provide empirical evidence in support of increased vertical coordination in hybrid governance when significant investments are made by a buyer specifically with the current supplier and When the levels of behavioral and demand uncertainty are elevated (Geyskens et al. 2006; Rindfleisch and Heide 1997; Williamson 1985; 1975). Hybrid governance requires greater information sharing between the buyer and the supplier (Celly et al. 1999), placing the buyer in a potentially adverse situation Concerning the safeguarding of information and assets invested and evaluation of the Supplier’s performance in complying with the contract. The buyer may be required to Share proprietary product and process information. Sharing such information, exposes the buyer to potential opportunistic behavior on behalf the supplier (Provan and Skinner 1 989), requiring safeguarding measures. In hybrid governance, as buyer asset specificity i1ICTeaseS, the buyer increases the level of vertical coordination with the supplier to reCluce the threat of opportunistic behavior and safeguard the assets by greater contract formalization (Buvik 1998; Cannon et al. 2000) and monitoring (Pilling et a1. 1994). In relationships where it is difficult for the buyer to measure price and delivery performance, Heide and John (1990) showed that buyers increased vertical coordination With the supplier by increasing monitoring and verification efforts. Houston and Johnson (2000) found that performance ambiguity led to increased vertical coordination between a 85 buyer and supplier in the formation of a joint venture. Strong forms of hybrid governance, such as joint ventures and alliances, allow buyers to protect their proprietary assets and monitor the supplier’s performance through joint ownership and risk sharing (Heide 1994). Consistent with prior research (Andersen and Buvik 2001; Buvik and Gronhaug 2000; Combs and Ketchen 1999; Heide and John 1990; Joshi and Stump 1999), the results of this research indicate that buyers utilizing hybrid governance adapt the governance with their current supplier by increasing vertical coordination, in the form of contract adjustments and increased monitoring and verification efforts, with the supplier to protect assets invested with the supplier and reduce behavioral uncertainty when the Stl‘ucture of the network changes. Increased vertical coordination allows the buyer to PI‘Otect the assets invested through increased interaction with the supplier to reduce POtential ex post opportunistic behavior and the misuse of proprietary assets and leakage of information to the new customer (Wathne and Heide 2000). Increased vertical cOOrdination can also occur in the form of increased monitoring of the supplier and verification efforts (Heide and John 1990). Monitoring and verification reduce the buyer’s behavioral uncertainty and increase the likelihood of the supplier meeting cost, gnality, and delivery targets preventing disruption of assembly and excess inventory 62 88930 Bo Z 55930 302 eczema—m nuggets—om owns-unam— Bo Z nuggets—om 9:3»: Que...— < ashram Exam m 3&5 580330 302 < 3&5 550550 302. G 58830 bzmmsm 58830 D 88830 Saddam Saddam \ m 68330 < 88830 8.39m Saddam . x3502 3822.0 262 3:259. 525 £033: .826 E 3:925 co gazes—.5285 P 2:2“. 171 Figure 2 Governance Costs as a Function of Asset Specificity* S M(k) X(k) H k Market ( ) 5 Hybrid 8 g Hierarchy a S e I l I l | , I l l l l l l o k, k 2 k Asset Specificity *From Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), "Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives,"Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (2), 269-296. 172 gm”? ‘- ._-_. - a 0 0 O 0 1 2.833 Z a 5 3:95an mafia 173 —-.-—--~~ "II-"'--' | "’ ‘ “ ’l ‘- ‘0 ‘\I. 'l \ l \\ II \ I \ I \ I \ I \ I \ \ \ ‘ \ \ s I I I I I I I s I \ I \ I \ I \ I, ‘\ ’ ‘ I"-' '|“ l ‘ I" “‘ "'l'||al 56:an xcogcaomtc> Bog Bonanza N SF “U Eczema TEE. Hm c988 sum :38 “< page: c.3332 .353» v same. ‘ s -" -----—- 174 a .Na .25 a. n1. 1.. _rli bacon x8362 .8:&=m Sham .8980 . . 55880:: >826on mcmmenoczm a Na _2 _m _eomwofienooh guacam— QEmaouflem a .% .ESI Sham .333 a .Q as: ommm :uE . . v: ”832F223 3580 a Na 55 2 3:353: panacea eoufiwoufi eosefiwcooo \ Exam soak; 35> “one: . mm 8§Eo>o z / ”Oggowsnm NE Exam / 58583 _E commas Sham 0: bfiefio 88830 Bo Z com—mmsm Emacs —a0muuh¢o£.~. m Baum... 175 25 cognac $56629 3 gauche 2a moSeEg 68 8:08ch mavens—mega: 8.380 88:80 «0 09C. ”bier—00:3 ”.3090on commas C m 7.5 owgoxo 5:3 com—5 5 38.280 Ammo _ v 33882 a. accum— coconom £23.. Engages 05023 com 3833? E Swag—0&0 amfiawe manna—women new Emgoofi Stop a 023%. £80: Feces—om flcoggoo creams 3 Bone Ewsofi SmMSEREO magma? E gauche": bomb: 0.8 308800 «8.5: 180328 x H8580 x 825E580 c>u§naoo $8.5.“ Queue—8 x 8253580 3:989:00 223.80 beam .650 08 E x «SEES 3383800 A ~ SHE Engage 3322— oumEstonno com 03835 ”mecca 3.8322 x “8.280 3:65:00 am $30.8 beam 28 3 80.382 $8.8: _eaouflom “cogcou E uoeeEo>ow 83: mo aeogafig crucifix SESEOQQO ”Eu—Egg 05383800 308 new Rwoq ace—250 as 3.534 mwfiefim mov— 32€z§> .5239:— 303325 «515365 38280 3.8.5.3. meme—5m _aoEa—Em «382.com— umeU actuamaeah w 03.; 176 08800—8 «0 :0:8w008 00000.88 3650000 00000 5:5 :0883800 8 888.008. _8:08:0.:>:m 5:030: 8:085; Sana 58880:: 3808588”,— 0038800080: 8500 380800 00 5:388 05 00200800080.— 588008. 35:88:80 20:30:88 88598 8 36:60.? 00000 :8: 208800.858 889» x bmuwmooqm 0000< 5830008. 0:80.» 08800.8 380$ mm 38800:: 3:030:0m 00:0:028 :008w005 3:030:0m mbmowmooam “003‘ 3.838 .00 002 Ammo: :080::< 08:80:03: 80:0828 8 5:08:88 8.5.58 880% 2 0:00— 38800:: 3808:0880 ::0 5808008: 80330: .«0 3:00:85 08:80:03: .800008008 8 00:08:38 8.608 880% 00 0:00. 36:60am 00000 5:3: 5:5 5:08.800 8 58800:: _flomzfiom 388.808. _S:08:0:_>:0 x 38800:: _80330m 58800080 SEHE 0030:0520: 3:030:00 x b83030 .002 80:00.:0zan 5:08:88 8.5028 9 :0020: 58800:: _8:08:0h>:m 85:88 0:380: 288 3033000 00 Ago—$0000 0003‘ 5:08:80... 85:25 53:60.; 0003‘ :5 3:08:02:— fi>=m a. :080::< 0w:_::_h >3— E0zumua> 80:53: 3033...; 0:0::0n0::~ 0:00:00 Amy—0:22 3.803 a 03.; 177 Emma EB 8x88 35:28:: >58 mo aomwom 5 8562885 bmoEoomm mugfiowg nousnwammv “covaoqgfi 3me :38 $5 82603 5m .0520 “8959?: 9:6me ”noumzaobbmv 382, 35:20 A23: 513.50 22:85 @8832: um: mug—«bum 95.? 35:30 vozuwoufi 8255 5858on Homm< 9383:: mo 33 a. cofiovfix cocoaag Row .«0 oohwov 9 F328 3033on mm Sagano 8539.8 300 mo>u35m8afi ..30503558 58 Swastonqo m3— »mEmE 8888—8 8th Swag—0&0 3 @822 Eggnog mm @5838: _Eogmnom Sens mo>uScomoa2 bag—3:: _Sogmnom .Eouaoflsaua Emgfioqqo 9 v8.22 5:39.85. _Saofiaogam 3&3 0888—3 225609 mm bfimfiam ~83 Swastano MDBEoon ~82 voamuwofim mo 83 $3: 5&3: mafia—F.— »oz Amvo_aam._a> 23.52—2— Eozata> «no—E235:— tnzgu 3.85.5. 8.25s _ as: 178 023000—00 05 00 000805.800 0030.00 .23 000060000 0_ bag 0050 030000200 05 5 00003003008 00 8003.506 05 00 0008:8800 3 0030—0 $050000 00mm< 0.083.505 0000.00.“ 00.“ 00350000 .00 00000000m 305000 m0 .0903 .«0 00.000000m ”00000808800 >030?“ .«0 0000000?“ Awnmnav 0030:0020.— gn 0050 05 m0 0025:5000 02000020.— 530288 .«0 00000003 .0055 5 0.003050% .«0 0000000000 05 0000008 380 05 0. 0008:8800 5300—83.— mbmowmoam 00000 000 Egoflafiwfi 3.00: 000 >0 m0wv03 bfimfiam 00mm< {002003002 .«0 00000000m $30.50on 0003‘ .«0 0008:8800 563 0% 0000002 00095 00 00: 0800000..“ 00000000.; 0000.“ 00: 58800000 000 bBEBQm 00000 m0 000008005 €858: EEEB x hzommoam 0002 ”53800050 30008000300 x bmomfiam ANN. TE 0003 Soaoswoa 0050800; 003030000500 00083:: 000800—00 00 0030800000000 5580000: 3003003" 200300358 000200 3033000 bmowmooam 00000 .flgdoflnaafi 00002, ”5880000: Esauogam 0:83 000800—00 A333 £03.35 3 0032—8 35800000120320m 000800—00 00003005 $22302? 0003 00089.5 m0 003 0% 0000092 awa‘mufih m3— A$0Eafa> 00000059 3033...; «00000000.: 008050 @0050< 80:80 _ 03.? 179 $030000 .00 m_0>0_ 000000 000 1003000 .8002? _000000 00 000003.000 00 0000000000005 0000—0000200 0 03000000000 00mm< ”8020000230 090800000 00000000000005 ”00300008 00000000000000— 5:000:00 00:0»:00 x 002000000 #00300 Z 5:000:00 0000m050 0 000009 #003002 3500300 00:0?30 20:00:00 010300 Z ”b00000 x8302 3000000000: 0000000000300 00 3650000 0000< 550000000 .800800030m 000000000000 00000000 500000000 00030 Am _ NUS 0020000030 0200000005 :80 00080 0 005. 00000—03 000—008 >00» 00000 00000 00080000000 000 5:30 00000000 $20050 .00 0000000003 0.5% 00000000 x 00000 000000000000 0 bt0>00 00080000005 $0230 00000000 x 00000 000000000050 60000 000000000000 00 b.0005» 00000000000m 30:30 00000000 00 300050 000000000040 ”b0000w00000: 00800000 $500380 8300000 5000000 0030000 200000000000 0&00 5:30 0000000Q M00000 00000000850 00002000 0000050 000000000050 Ave—HS 00300000300 8.3.55 0000000000002 383 0220 0 00:5 £0w00m .002 0000.50 080 3033000» 0000000009 30300000» 0000000005 00000000 3020.2 8.0008 m 030,—. 180 $000 00.0000w00 000 300000000 00000 000500 0200000000 05 00000000. 08000 30000—30 3000 00000030 00 0000—00 b32000 0100500000 3008000$0m 0000 00000030 00 0000—00 3030000 0_ 0000000000 0000.0. 0000 00000092 0000000000 0 0050080 0 00050000 .0004 00000000000 0000.000030m 50050000 0000< AmomuS 0030000300 5:00.0on 880 .080 0 52 000.000.00.000 000.0000 00 802000007: .00 0000.00 05 00000000 0000000000 000000 0.3000020.— 05 00 00_0> 000 0300.00 05 0000000 00 0000 hp 000000 0_ 00000000 .05. 000009 «0080000000 00000000 000000 0000000000 0103002 000000000000 0000000 9 0000—00 000 000000000000 _000080050m 00080000000 0000000 00 0000—00 5030000 0300:0000 000044. 8.0080 :80 025:0 0 003 005050 3. 30300.09 000000009 30300.00» 0000000005 08080 3.20.2 00.0.80 0 as; 181 003050 2 0202 0:029, 82% 8888.030 E3: b30000 0000000020 00000: >000:on 000—002 ”000000000000 00000: _000000 0000xm 000—000 0% 0=0m 00000w00£ 0000000, 00 000000 >_0>00w00 0_ 3000000000 000000Q 000003000 _00000> 00 0000000 0.300000 00 0000000000 ~000w2000000. 0000003000 00000000 0008 000003000 .00 00w0000>00 0000 000000000 _00000> 0000 300300 0.0 00303000 000003000 _0w04 5000000000 0000an GENE _00000> 000— 0.00.» 0000000000 ”00000000000 0.000000 0000000000 _00000> @003 00302 00w0000>00 000300070 000003000 _00000> 500300000 ~000w0_0000001 000 b00000 _0w0q 0% 000030m £0000m 030 00 0000000000 .00 000w00 0.0 .0 30000000 000000000 QUE 05008.3 302.0280 B 8208022 000 a @000 0000253 b0>00w00 00000.00 00 00003000— 00000w00£ _00000> 00000000000 _00000000030m 00000000 000 00 00.02 0% 00000E0~0m 00000300 _000000 00 0000—00 b0>00m00 00 3000 000008 3000000000 .8008000>0m 3000.00 000000000005 03000000 000003000 _0020 00000 0000000 03000.00 0000000 000—002 ”0000 $075 0 000 00 box: 0008 000 00000 0000 ”0000000000 00000000005 0000—0000 $00000 @003 00000005 300000000 00000 0< 000003000 _000000 £00 0000000 ”000000000 0000< 5 00000300 _000000 0080M 0% §0_0< 0000000..— .mov— 30300000, 00000000G 30.000000» 0000000000: 00000000 3005000 90.0003 a 030,—. 182 000000000000 .00 000000000 00 0000—00 0000000000 00 000030000 000000000000 00308 5T5 000000000000 0000000 ”0000300 0000000005 00000000 00000000 .00 000000000 00 0000000 $00000 0>00000xm ”0000000000 0000 000095000 .00 300: 000C >00>00w00 00 00000000 0000000005 0000000000000 .00 000000000. 0009 50003000 000000000000 000000000 0000000000002 0% 00002 .00w00m 3000000000 00000 00 0000000 x00>00w00 000 000000000 000000000 000 00000000000000 .00000 0000006 0000000 .0000 000000..“ 00000000 _0000000000 000000000 000005 0000000000000 000 .00 0w< 000000000000 3 0.0 .00 0000m 00000000000 8 0000000 00 000000000 000000000 1 0000000m 0000000000000 00000000 000000000 00000 00 0000000003 ”00000000000 0000009 :0qu 00300000000 0000000 300000000 00 000000000000 0000000 00000000 000000m ”0000 00000000000 05 .00 00000 000 5000000000 0000000000000 000000m 000000000000 0000.0. 00 00000000>00 00000 3005 0000000< 0000w0_000000 5000000000 0000. 00.000000 0.00z0m “00000000000005 00000000000000 00.000000 .00 0000000000000. 0% 000000m 000 00000000000 00 0000000 00 3000000000 00000000000030 000 000000 00 0000000 00 3000000000 00000000000 000000000030m Aoomnfi 000000000000 $003 00000 0000000 000 0000000 00000 .00 00 D 0000000003 0000< 0000000 000006. 0003 0% 000m 0500.0 00! A000E0000> 00000000G 30.000000» 0000000000— 0000000 3000—000. 00.00.80 0 0300. 000 00 000.0 0000.0 0000 00008000000 000000 0>00 00.0. 0000 0000 0800 0000000000000 0000000000 00000 0 00000000000 000000 000000 00000 000000000 500000000: 00 00000000 0000000000 000 00000000000 00003000m ”00000000000 Am0Nu00 388 00000 >9 0% 000000000 0000 0000000000 0000< 00000 00.00 0000000000 ”0000000000 00000 000000 000000 00000 00000005 00000005 00000 .00 0000000 000030 00003 00 00000000 000300000 00 Am 0 «"00 00000 0000000000 0000000000 00030.0 000000 00000 0000000000 0000< 000000 000000 00000 Good 0000000005 0000000000 0003000000 00 0000000000 00 0000 0000000000: 0000000000300 00 0000000000 0000 00000000000 00 0000 0000 026 00000000000 Ave—H00 b50008: 00 30000 0000000000000 00 000000000 3000000000000 00000000 0000000000: 0000000000300 000 0000000 000000960 0000301— 0. 0w00m 000000000000 .00 000000000 00 00000000 000300000 00 000000000 000000000 0000000000000 .00 000000000 00 00000000 000300000 00 w00000 03020000 000080 000000000000 .00 000000000 00 $0000 0005 00000000 >00>00w00 00 00000000 0005 00. 0000000 00900 0u000000 00v— A00030000> 000000020 30.000000» 0000000000— 00000000 000000030 00.2.80 0 200.0 184 000000000 00 00000000 00000000 .00 0000000000000 0000 .030 00 0000000000 00000000000000 000 0w00 00 0000000000 00000 0000000 0003 0000000000 w0000b000 00000000 0000000000 0000000000. ”0000000000 00000 GENE 000000000000 .00 0000300000000 0000 .0000 00 0 0000000000 0000000000000”.— M000000000 00 0000000000 00000000000000 000 300 000.0000 w000000000 ”0000000000 0000< 0000000000 000000000 00 0000000000 00000 0000000 0003 030000000 .00 000000 ”0000000000 00000000000000 000 _000w00000000. $0000 030m 030 00 0000000000 00000 0003 0000000000 00300 00000000 00 030000.00 00 0000000>0m 00000000000 0000000000 000000000 0. 500000000 00000 x 0000000>0w 000000000 00300 0000000000 ”00000000000 Aw0n0v 00 0000000 000000000 000 000000000 0800000000000 ”0000000000 00000000 300000000 80000 0000000000 000 00000000000 000000 0000000000 00300 0000< ”0000000>0w 00000000000 -00 .00 00000000w00 0000w00m 0% 000005 000000000000 0080 0000000000000 0000000000» 00000 0003 000000000000 a 05 003.00 00 00:8 0080030 Amamuav 08000 0000000000 00000000000 wfiw00000 00 0000000000 00000 00 000000030 00 000000 0000000000 ”000000 _00000000 00 0000000000 .00 00000000050 0000< ”000000 0000000000 000 .000000 00 000000030 ”0000000000 00000 00.000000 0000000000 00000 0000 0003 000000000000 00 000000030 ”000000 0000000000 00 0000000060 8008 000000000 000000000 0000< 00000000000 00000000000 0000< ”000000030 .000000030 .00 00000000 000 d. >0Q .0300m 00000000 00M 300000000, 000000000— 30300.0000» 0000000000— 00000000 30000000 000.080 0 2000. 185 0000000000000 0000000000000 00 00000 0000000000 0000 x0 m0000300 00 03000000 00000 0 00000000000 00000000, 500000000 000000.00 000>00 030 0003 0000000000000 0000000000000 00 000w00 000 00000 0000000000 0000 000 0000000000 000030000 00 0000000000000 0000000> 00 0000000000 0000< ”000000000000 00000?» 00 0000000000 0000< ”0000000000 000030000 00 000000000000 000000> ”0000000000 0000000000 00 0000000000 0000< 300000000000 0000000> 000000000000 00000 0000000000 0000 00 0000000000 ”0000000000 0000< 00075 000000000000 00000 .0005 0800820 0 0800 00000000000 0000000> 0000000< 0% 030m 00000 0000000000 0000 000 00 0000000 000000000 00 0000000000 00000000000000 000000000 032000000 w00.00000.000000 0.00000 000 .00 0000000000 000 00 00000 0000000000 0000 000 000000 00000000000000 0000000 000000000000 000000000 000 0000000000 00000 0000000 00000 0000000000 0000 000 000000 0000000000 0000000> 000000000 000 00000000 00000 0000000 00000000000 00000000000000 00000 0000000080 0000 00 ”0000000000 0000< 0: T5 00.008002 5:00.505 880 0050 00:00.00 030 300000000» 000000009 00000000000» 0000000000— 00000000 A0000000< 00.0080 0 0000.0 186 000000000 00 00000000000 0000000> 000000000 0000 00 0000000000 00000000000000 0003 00000000000 0000000> 00 0000000 000000000 00 0000000000 0000000000200 .300 00 0000000000 00000 0003 0000000000 0000000000300 00 000000000000 00000020 00 0000000000 0000< 0000000000000 00000000, 00 0000000000 0000< 000000000000 0000000000300 00 0000000000000 0000000> ”00000000000 00000000000000 0 0000000000 000000. ”0000000000 .00 0000000000 0000000000000 0000000> 5T5 80.008002 00000 0000000000 0000 000 0000000 0000000000000 0000000000300 0000000000 00 883 00 0000— 0000000000 0000000000. 00000 0000000000 0000 000 00000000000 0000< 000000000000 0000000> 000 0. a. 030m E000w0000 000 00000000000 00000000000300 00 0000000000 000 w000000 00000000000000 00.0 00000000 0000 00 0000000000000 00000000 .0wE 00 0000000000 00000 0003 00000000000 00000000000 00000000000000 00 0000000000 0000000> 00 0000000 000000000 0000< 0000000000 00000000000. Amw T00 0000000000000 00 0000000000 0000000000300 ”00000000000 0000000000300 0000000000 00 883 .300 00 0000000000 00000 0003 00000000000 0000000> ”0000000000 0000< 000000000000 000000000 w0000000 0.0 030m 0&000000 00v— ~000_00000> 000000030 0000000000» 0000000000- 00000000 30000000 8.00000 0 00000. 187 00000000000 0>00000 :03 0000000000 00000000 00 000000000 0000000000000 0000000000300 >00— 000 000000 0000000 300 00000 0000000000000 00 0 00008000000 0>00000 000 :03 0000000000000 00000000 00 000000000 0000000000000 0000000000200 030 0000 000000 00.000000 0003 0000000000000 00 0 000000 0000000000 000000000000 000000000025 000000000000 00:000m 00000000000 000040 $00.00 000000000000 00000 00000 00 0000000>0w .00 0000.0 0000—0 880 080050 a. 00000< 000000 000000 0000000 20000000 .8300: as, 500 002.08% 00000 0300000000 00.0 000000» 00 00000000 00000000 00000000000 0000000000 00000 3000000000 0003 0000 0000000000 00000 0300000000 00.0 000% 00 00000000 00000000 000000000 000000 20000000 000000000 0003 0000 000000 00.000000 2000000000 0000000000 00 000000w 00 00000000 00000000 0000000000 0000000000 00000 30— 0000000 0003 0000 000000 00.000000 200 0000000 000000000 00.0 000000w 00 00000000 00000000 00000000000 0000000000 00000 3000000000 000 000000 0000000 20000000 000000000 0003 9000000000 00000000 000000000 00 000000.000 02 00000000 00000000 00000000000 00000000000 0000< GENE 000000000000 3000000000 0000000000 00 000000 00.00000m :80 250 0 00.500 00:00:00 0&0 0000000000, 000000000 000.000.0000» 0000000000— 00000000 0000000000 00.0080 0 as; 188 0000000000 00000 00 00000000 000300000 00 0000020000000 0000000 .00 0000000000 0000 00000000000 0000m0000000H 00000000 N000000000 00000000000 .00 00000 00 0000000000— 000000>00000000 0000000 .00 0000000000 0000000000000 0000000000 0000< 000000000000 000030000000. $.qu 000000000000 00000 00000 0000000000000 00 0000000000000 0000000> 802000002500 0 090800 .000 0000000 0w00000 000 00 00000>0m 000 000000 0000000000 200 00000 .00 0000000 >02 000300000 000 000000 0000000 030 0003 0000000000000 0300000 00000002 000000000 0008 0000000>0w 000—0000 0003 000000000 000300000 000.00 00 .000000 .00000000 000 000000 00.000000 0E0 00? 0000000000000 000000 0000000000 00000000 00000.0 00 00>000 00000 w000000 00000 03000000000 00? .000000 0000000000 00 000>00 030 00000000 000000 00.00000 30— 0003 000000000000 030000000000 000 002000000000 000000000000 0000000 .00 000000005 000000000 00w00000 0000000000 00000 00000 ”000000 0000000000 000000000 0000000000 ”0000000000 0000< Amvvufi 0000000000000 0000000000 00 0000000000000 0000000000 0000 0 0 000000000 .00. 000000 0000000000 00000000 000 003 0000000>0w 00000000000 .00 00000000 00 0000000 000000000 00 0000000000 0000000000 0000000000200 300 000 000000 00.00000 30— 0003 000000000000 000000000000 00 0000000 00030000 0000000 _000000000 00 0000000000 0000000000 0000000000300 030 000 000000 0000000 0003 0000000000000 00 0 6.0080 8003 00000000 0% 0000000 .000000 00000000 00% 0000300000» 0000000000 00000000000, 0000000000— 00000000 00020.2 90.00000 0 0—000. 189 0000 0000000000000 000 00000008 .m00000w000 00 000000.000 00000000 0 0>00 000000000000 .00 0000.00 3 0 NH0 0000 00m .05H0 00000 0000000008 00000 0000000002 00000 00: 0000000000000 0000 .0000000000 0000000000 ”00000 0000000002 00003000000 0000000000000000000 A000: 0000002 00 000—00 03300000 00 000000000000 000000 0000000005 “0000000000 0000000000000 00 0000000000000 .00 0000000000— 0000000000 $.0H00 0000000000 000000000 00 0000000 0000000000 0000003000— 00008000000 000 A000: 00300000 00 0000000000 0000< 0000000000 000000000 000000m 00000000000 0000< 0000000000 00000005 0000030 00 000000 0000000000 000000> 00 0000000 000300000 00 0000000000 0000< 0000000000 00000 .00 0000000 0030— 00 000000000 00 00000 000000 0000000000 00000 :03 003085. 09858050 0 053085. 0002508060 $80000 03008.0 0 0030 000000000 0003 0000000000 0000< 00000000000 _000000> 00000000000 0000< 00000000 000 00 0002 000000000 00 00000 000000000 000000000000 00000 00 0000000 0000000 000300000 00 0000000000 0000< 000000000000 00000 0.0.80 00000000 0000000200 00 0000000 00000000000000 0.0300000 00 0000000000 0000< 000000000 0000000000000 0000000000 0000< a. 0000000m .0000 00000000 00! ~000_00000> 00000000G 0000300000» 0000000005 0000000 000000000 90.00000 — 030,—. 190 00000000000 00000000000 00 0000000000000 00 0000000 000300000 00 0000000000 0000< 0::000 0202000 ”0000000000000 0000000005 0000000000 0000000000002 ”0000000000 0000000000 0000< 0000000000000 0000300000 00000000000 .00 000800—0000 0000 00 0000000000 00000000000 00000000000 A000H00 00000000000 A0003 00000m 0000— 0000000300 000030000 00005 0000000000 .00 0000002000— 000000000 0000000000000 000000.500 _00000> 0% 020$ .0009 00000000 0000000 00 0000000 000300000 00 0000000000 0000000000300 0000000000000 _000000 $0000 0000 00 000 000 00000000 0000000000 00000000 0000000000 00008000000 A000n00 00000000 0000 a. .0000: 0000000000000 000 000000000000 00000 00000> 00005 ”00-003000000000000 000000000000 00000 000000 .0005 00008000 0000000 00 0000000 000300000 00 0000000000 0000000000000 00~0u=0 0000000000 00 000000 0000000000 00000000000000 000000000000 0000 0.0300000 00 0000000000 0000< 00000000m 0000000060 00000000000 0000< 0000000000 000000000 A0003 000009 00.00000 000000000000 00 0000—00 000>000w00 A0003 0000w0Z 00 0000000000000 0000 0000000000 000000000000 0% 0000000003 0§00000 00v— 000030000> 0000000000 0000300000» 00000000000 0000000 000000000 0.2.30 0 2.3 191 00000000000 00 000—00 00030000 00 0000000000 00000 0000000000 0000 00000020 000 00300 0000 0000000000 0000 00000000 0000000 0000 00000 000000 00 0000—00 000300000 000000000 00000 000000 00000005 000000 00 0000000 000300000 0:55.080 08 000000 000000>00 0000 2000 000000 302 Sang 00800 9% 0000000000 00000 000000 00000000— 000000 0000000000 300.0 00 000000050 000000m A0000: 000G 0000000000 w00000000 ..000 00000000 0003000 00000000. 00000 0000000000 0000 0000003 000000000 .00 0000000300 000 000000 0003000 00000000. 00000000 00000 00003000 "00000000 000000000 ”000000000 @0700 00000000 0000 0000000 0. 00 0000000000 00000 0000000 0000 0000000050 ”000000 ”0000000000 0000< 00 00000005» 000000m A0000: 000D $50.00 00! 0000300000’ 00000000G 30.000005 0000000000— 0000.0000 0000000000 00.0080 0 as: 192 00:0000 0.00 08.0.0 000 000000000 0.00.0 0.00000 630000005 000 0003.000 0003 005000000 030 000 000000 _000000 000000 00>0.0 00 0000 0005 003.000 .30. 00 000050000 00000 0003 0008 E000 E _000000 ”0000000000 00000000000000 0 0000800 03?. 50300085 0 50090000 0000< ”000000000 0000000 0 000050000 0000< ”0000000000: 0000000000025 M00000000 _0000000 3 wmna 300—50000000— 300000000 0050 000200 .00 0008 0000000 00003000000 0000< 0000 30000000000 000000 80 0 0000000 00020 datum—hows 00000005 005.: 0030.00 00000 0000000000 0000 00 00095 00032 00000 .00 000000003000; 00000 0000000000 0000 00 0.0030— 0030 00000.00 $000.00 0000000000 00000 0000000000 0000 xm 00000 0000000000 0000 xm $30 00805 9.5 0000000030000 00 0000000>0w 00:00.00 0000mm ”00000. 5020000000 0000< .00 0000 00 000000 3003 000 0% 00mm— 000000 0000—0600000 5 00000000300 6 000 000003.000 map—0.0000000 _000000000000 .00 000 90 0900000 00000000000 0500000000 03000000 any 000% 0020000 :25 0003 m0000000000 00 00000 00 0000000000 30 0000—0000 .00 000 000000 0005 0000000000 00000000 A: 00 000 00000 0000000000 00300 0>00 0000000 _. 0000 00000000000. Gene 0000000 93 0000000000 0000< 00 00000005» 00:000.,“ Ea: 0g0 0050.0... 080 30300000» 0000000009 30300000» 0000000000— 0000000 30000.? 00.0080 0 00.0.0. 193 008.00 000005000 000 000000000 0.000000 0000000000000 0003000 02000020.. 000 000500000 000000020 .00—000,0 00835 0000000000 000 000.000 000000000000 000000000000. 0003000 030000200 000 0000—003 000000000000 00:003— 00825 8000.500 000 30000 00 0000000000 000.5 0003000 00000000000 Amwnfi 0.0000000 .00 300 3 000 000000? 0000000000 00000000 00000000 0000000005 00000000000 0000< 00000000000 0300.00 0000‘— 0% 00000.00 0000000000 00 0000000 30300000 00 0000000000 0000< 000000000080 30000 00 0000000 30300000 0000000000 00000 @015 0.00 000000000 00000 000 00000000000 0 b00080: 0000000000025 0000000800 000 00000000000000 0003000 0000000000 0000000000 3000000000 0000< .00000 0300000000000 000 000 00000000000 0000000000>0m 00000> 000000020 0005 20000000000 000008000>0m 0003000 000000000. 3003 0:00 0000000000000 000 00 00.00000 000000000000 00000 0>00 00000000000 0020000 00 0000000000 0003 0030000000 b00000 00 0000—00 00 0000000 003000—00 30300000 00 300000000 0000< 090000.000 .00 00000Q 0000000000 000 00 0000000300 00000 0>00 0000000000 0000000000 03 000—0000 Gonna 0003 330000000 00000 00 0000000 2 00000.00 300000—00 00000000 00000000000 00 £003 30300000 00 0000000000 000000. 0005 .00 000000 0000000000 0000< 000000000000 0300000 00000004. 00 0000 0000000,.— h0v— 4000300000» 000000009 000300000» 00000000000— 0000000 3.000000. 00.00000 0 030,—. 194 000000 00.00000 0000000 00 0000000300 EmO .00 000000. 000 00003 000 .00000000 Ana—H00 0000000000000 @003 0000 00 05 0000080000 00000 0000. 500000000 0000< 00000000008000 00000000 000000005 000.. 00 00000 0300830 39 00 08000 20 0000005 3000000000 00000000000000 30— 000 5000000000 000030000 000 300000000 00000 0000 000000030 00000 .00 000000 000 00 0000000 30300000 00 0000000000000 0000000030 5000000000 300000000300 00 0000000000 Cbfiufi 03000030 30000 0000< 000000000000 00003000m 0000000000000 00 000000 000 00 0000000 30300000 b00008 0000000 500000000 _00000000030m .05 .00 0000000000000 $00: 0000000< 00 0000000000 0000080000000.— .00 000000030 .00 000009 500000000 0000< 3 000000030 .00 000009 00 0000000 0000000 000 00 0000000000 0.00000> 000 0000000 000000000 000000000 00000 00000 > 00 0000000000 0.00000 > A000000> 00000> 000 00 0000000000 mm 000 00000000 0.0030000 .00 0000000000 000 00000> 00 0000000000 5000000000 000000000030m 000 "00 0000000000 000000000 000000000 00000 0000000 0000000000 000000000 500000000 0000< 0000000000 0000.0 @003 0000000 0000000,.— »0v— 30.000000, 00000000G 30300000» 0000000005 00000000 3000000. 00.0080 0 030.0 195 05080 0300—000 .00 0000000: 000 0000000 000 000 000.0 00 00000000000000 0050 00.0 00000000 0000000 0000000000 0000”.— ”000000000000 000000000002 ”0000 000000000 00m 500005000 000000 02000000 00000000 .00 000000 0000000 00 0008 £07.00 0000000200 000000000 .0800 E 200 00000000 00000 0000000000. ”000.5000 00:00.00000 A000: 00000m 0 0.00 0000000 0000000000 00000005 000000 03000000 00 003 0000000000000 00 00000 0000 E 000000 0300—000 00 0000 .0003 000000000000 00000 00 0000>00 002 00 :03 00000000000005 0000 _000000000 000 000000000000 000000000300 .00 0000000000 0000000000000 0000000 .00 0000000000000 000 00 0000000 0000>00 0000000 000 0000000000 0000000000000 000000000000 00000 000 _000000 00 0000 000000000 0000.0 0000000000 00000 00 :05 0000 00000000 00000000000300 0000000000 0 3000000000 0000000000000 5000000000 0000< 000000000000 00000 000 000—0000 00 500000000 _00000000030m 0000 000000000 0000.0 00000000000000 ”00000000000800 ANNNHE 000000000000 A083 00000000 00000 00 :03 00.00 000200000 0008 0000000000000 0000 0000000000 00:00-0000m 00 00000300 .0030 00000.00 03— 30300000» 000000020 30.000000» 0000000000— 00000000 30000000 30.0003 0 030,—. 196 3.8% cougar? .8 88— 05 macho 83085 bBwBEa 858888; cougar? 8:996 33588 .8 838898 05 83888 b88280 mam—5888895 Esme—BEBE .8 3838896 beans“ confidante.“ ”358.823 :ouoa E838 _SnoEdEFGm com—nan» Gm ""5 85. 05 8385 Ban—95 on: was .8 382832: 3:83 man—macaw?— uozom 83: 8.35 05 >9 3:25ng £83m cocoa ~52 £935 .8 flfigmgfl 0&8on Lana E aouon 88b. 58m a. 020m 858m .8 bmfiaooflqou 9 8828 30383: Garcia fl bmommooam 8mg Saga .8 3533833— own—98x0 382582: .8 8938880 ”$885.8 .8 SENS wfizombo 2 332 33288 mm hon—:82 ”bio—Q88 838E 3598.522 8:8 3me bmoamooqm Emma 8:995 33085 882532: mfizombo 5858.? gamma 8:655 5.33 E cocooaoaun .22. a. 020: mam—mow 033—88 «0 80238:. 05 m3— ofi £082.35 98 cc 3895 Smoo 05 Same mfifiov 033—83 .8 woos—=8:— ofi 8.283 832 0:. .0288an .892:me $3: now—om 958390 E 81858 05 .8880 a. SEQ 620$ mam—:5— 8! 3833...; Hangman five—nut!» 2828965 28:80 3.85.2 €3.88 — «EFF 197 8888.58: 9 88.2 58388: m: &::888: 38:82:55 88:88:88: 9 88—2 A8580: m: &_::::8 8:: &::380:: 38:89:28 .8 8:882: 8:88:88: 0828: &8:80% 8%: 8::95 5 3:22:85: 8&5 8:88:88: 8 88:2 53:80: &8:::oo x 8:888: 38:89:55 S8583 x &8:88% 8mm< A2289»: own: m8&5 m: &8:::oo :8 &8:88% $25888: §:ofi:oh>:m 37:: 35828—2 33: 8mm: 8::95 8 :28225 88:88.58: $28588 8mm< 8:8.8&5 :82m 8% 288: 82.088: 8:33 88 85:8 8&5 88885 wgoflngfi 835-5 :8 8:288:88 8&5 85:3 8&5 o. 8222 3388: m: 2:8: 80:22 :8 >558on 8.8m 8&5 .8 8:822:— 8588 8&5 8828: .0858?” 8mg 8&5 5 8828:: 028288: 88 8835.: 2: 8: 5:8: 88:32 x 333 mm 85:8 _mo:8> 2:88 2 :5: 8 8:8on 8&5 8285888 88 328 8:8on 80:? 8:8: :8 80888: 8:83 8&5 888: 3:08:85 2.38: 3:88:32 33: 8568: 8: m: z .250: .8 oo85< 88 85:8 m.8&5 88me 8:8on 8&5 8:8-8&5 5 8:82 53 a. 8:82 «ME—Er.— 8! 38538:» 88895 383:8; 88:28::— «8880 385.3. 8.2.8: _ as; 198 8383898 30: 8 88033 .8 388: 32 :8 :8: 8 88823 8:5 8:38:88: 83.33898 80: 8 88283 .8 388— :8: 8 8888.83 3:88:00 800 8383880 30: 8 88833 .8 £26— 32 :8 83888.80 80: 8 .8 808885 83.: 83888.50 8:38:88— 80:88:00 AONNHE 3:580:52 :3: 8 8828 &8:8on 83¢. 30: 8 8883—5 8:0 58:8on 8388 888:5 8:03.885 A508 .8: 88::8 8:30.&_o:B 9 @0882 2:83 8:3. Amamufi 28:2, 88“ 38:3 83:82; &o>:_mo: m: &8:803 83< v.38.» 8:30.553 b85803 83< m38> 8:30-»:053 a. 88.85 8888 2:82, 8:3 2 88:2 &o>8wo: m: 8888: 88:28 2:89» 88 .q 8 88—2 x8388 m: 885:8 8:88:88: Ezua 88:28 2:83 88% 2 88—2 28:? 888.8: 58588:: 2:82, 8:2 m38> 8003 A8380: 8 &8:803 83< 88_. m38> 82800 8838585 58:883. 88a: 8288 8:83.885 83:52. a. 88:05 8:85.: hov— 88358> 8282.85 88.58:; 88:28::— 8280 385.3. A9883 m 258,—. 199 80828800 6:095 ..0 82.00800 0. 00.0.0. 30>...qu 0.0 08.0.. 180323. 808.8800 8:09.... ..0 003000.09 05 0. 00.80. 303.600 0... 0808.008. 3.80% 02.0888. 80.89% 808.8800 5:003 ..0 008000.00 0.. 0. 00.20. b03390 0... 0808.008. 008008.... {0:83. 0.08.000 tom—9.0 x 3.2.6000 .0000 03—50% $8.00 800320.. x 3.05009. .0000 {0.30% 5.3.600... .0000 04.0.8.0. 0. 3.2.6000 .0000 .2895 ”0.08800 £0.38“. ”0.8.0.. 280323. 80.8.8800 5.0....0000 .0000 010.50% .0200... ..0 0000080.. 5.06.0000 .0000 .0zaadm Chin... 3380020.. 8:00.885 .oco~. 00008.0 0% 9... >80 808080.50 .00.. x0 ..0 0.2.0. 30— .0 00800.00 00:08.0...00 0. 00.20.. 303.600 0. .00... .8282... 80.88.0000 .00.. ..0 ..0 .205. am... .0 00380300 03.300800 ..0 8080.6an 0.... 000080fi00 0.809888 ..0 80:02.30 0. 00.30.. 303.80.. 0. 000008000 _000 80880000 .000 0.0 ..0 £05. 30— 0.... am... 80.— 8 00800.00 005800.000 :0 0.8.3.8 0808.008. 2.80.3006. .8825 808080000 .000 ..m ”.00... 80835000 .808090.£ ”000003000 .000 ..0 00.00.56 _000 5.0....0000 .0me 3.0.35 3% _n5 00382.20. .0=0m...0>=m .moomv 00800.3. 0% 00.. .053... .3. 3030......» .00—8095 3030......» 80—809....— 3.0.800 3.3.3. 20.803 — 03.; 200 00300000800 30.00 ..0 0w0800.00 0... 3803000.. 880800.380 A . EH0. 0. 30.0.0. 308.000 0.0 388.000.. 0. 333080.000 ”388.0000 08.3 8.0000800... 880800.380 ..00 333000800. .0.0.>0..0m ”30.000000 8 008000.00 ..0 00300.08. 0... ..00 333000080. 00300000800 880800.38... ”333030.090 .0. 00300000800 .03.. 30.8.0000 .0.0.>0..0m. ..0 090800.00 00 30.0w 3.03.0000 .000... 0>30008 000.0> 38% 5.03 0% 8.0.. 0.000000 .00.... 0. 30.0.0. 30>...000 0. 38000000 .0.0.>0..0m 0.000030 .00.... 0. 30.0.0. 333.000 0. 38080000 .080800..>0m. 0039.80. 00.00 ..0 3.0000 ”080.9. 8.00 50.0.82 .8223... .00"... 0.000030 .00.... 0. 30.0.0. ”30.8.0000 .080800..>0m 0.000000 00303.30... .30 .V 30>...000 0. 3.03.0000 .000< 00.00 .00.... ..0 0080A. ”3.03.0000 .000... 0. 003080.... 3.03.00 8.03 .0. 8.0.. 80.08.0000 0. 30.0.0. 333.000 0.0 000300.80 .0300 080.000 .0300 8083000000 ..0 000303.840 80303.80 ASAHS 080808080 80.0....0000 0. 30.0.0. 308.000 .0300 0>.0.000 ..0 803000.00 .000000 w8080003 0. 90.0.0030 030.00008m 80.80.0000 88.0.0030 038000005 0. 80.80.0000 .33.. 8.0.. 800030800 .0..0000 .0 000300800 0. 30.0.0. 30>..0w00 .3800. 88m. 0. 0.00.800 ..0..0..0 ..0 003 0000000 .0. 00.. 30.00.0080.— 30388.» 8030000.. 3030......» 80.800000. 0.0.000 3.0.3.3. ._...000. . 0.00% 201 €033.53“. «ogfloo OH Ban—0.. .000”... 003000380. 303.000 0. 3.03.0000 800.... 80.800 ..0 003035 3.03.0000 .000< 8300-803. .50.. 300.00. .003 300 388800038808 00.0.003 ..0 0.0>0. 8.00088 3.3 30000300 0. 00300 8.0.. 300 3.03.0000 .0000 8.8008008 0003.03 0.3000380. 03H 00300 .80.. 300 3.03.0000 .0000 8.8008008 0003.03 0.3000380. 03. 00.000030 3.03.0000 .0000 w800080. 830000 8 .003 x 3.03.0000 .0000 88.00.8003. 380.8000 8.0.08 00.0.003 x 3.03.0000 .0000 0.800.808). 3.03.0000 .0000 .030000 .. 3.03.0000 .0000 8.8008003. ”830000 8 .00.... ”380.800.. 83.08 00.0.00n. 00300 .80.. 0. 30.0.0. 30>...000 ”3.03.0000 .0000 .03000m Avw.n0v 003000380. 300.. 0. 3.03.0000 .0000 88.00.8002 00300 .80.. 383.800 .0000 88.00.8002 830000.883 088m .3 .300. 08.00 .000380. 30.3 .0300 30.0.0. 3008.8 0.0 80.08.0000 300 0000300003 .000m .0: u... 08.00 .000380. 08.00 .00030.0. .3 30.08308 830000 30. .0300 30.0.0. 30>3.000 0.0 30.0.0308. 08.00 .080w0 80.08.0000 £00 .. 80.08.0000 300 0000300003 .0003 80.08.0000 800380.. ”0000300003 800m 300 0000300003 .035 3.0...< .3 .300 .. 000.30.... ~8v. 3030.8.» 8030000: 3030......» 803000030. .8800 303.0380. 3.800. — 030,—. 202 50505550 _05850 8 0050.. 305550: 5 358.605 _805050m 5050558 _05550 2 505505 3055005 5 3580005 3505055m 3505005 _503m50m 50505055 .0555 ”3555005 _5505505>5m Ammmnav 005055.505 55550 .50qu :8: 505 a £05 005080>0w 0500505 $505055 0. 005500 305025 5 350.5055 3505505>5m 0055550» 355050.505055 m0 005 2 50:50.. 305503 5 558 585,055 5050585 _05850 0. 005.00 305508 5 352.5050 500< 3.58.805 _8505505>5m 50505055 35550 ”355.5050 534 Ghana $05005 55050.5 .5 50505055 35850 88: 535 a. 025:5 .505 _05850 5098 05 .50 55.00 50553 0“ 0050.. 3025505 5 555530 50 505500 3055005 5 3505500 3585005 3505505>am 35850 00098 05 .50 _0550 .0052, 05 0820.. 3055005 05 55560.5 5050355 550 352.5050 502 3555005 50500505. ”3550005 3505505>5m 55500 30552, ”35050050 .0mm< Awmmuav 0.05850 .0098 .50 5.5500 3mm; 52M 55050050 .50 060505 50500005 050 95050050 x: 5003005 55505505 05 00500505 305505 3580005 550 352.5050 53¢ 55050050 x: x 35800053 ”55050050 5 x 558% .82 55050050 .50 050505 5050053 Ammvuav 55050350 5: 5 8000 50508.55 .50 20% 83.1850 5 50550502 .0555 awe—.55 5.: 3035...; 5055052— 350355; 50552—05:— 50500 30055< 8.5.80 5 2...; 203 0000500>0w 05005055000003 00 5000—00 3000025 05 500 50505055 5005000» 00 0000—00 3055000 .5 350000005 5505505500 0.00 350550000 00000 .00 5050000055 50505055 .0050? 00 0000—00 3055000 5 3050000005 550550525 350000005 550.500.5050 00 35050000 0009.0 00505055 305000.. 00 0000—00 ”35000005 _05050055m Aacvua A808 3055000 5 35050000 000044. 50505055 _00500> ”35050000 00030 5055000 35.00.0502 00:52 0% 503505 5055000000 00 0000—00 3055000 5 5505000550 05505000 0.000000%.“— 555000000 00 0000—00 3055000 5 0000555 500550 5055000050 50550000050 Ame—"5 000000505 00 000500 3035000 5 35000005 0550505 ”0000050 _05050 50 000000900 0003005 50.505 5055000 0000000055 5055000000 “3050000005 w55055055009 00000550 0500005 300: 005 _00500 _00030505 553 0000—00 3055000 5 305000005 _0003050m 350.0005 55005005200 00 350550000 _00500 000050 ”35000005 _0003050m 50050505 00 5000—00 3035000 ”35000005 550550525 83".: 5 35000005 350500$=m _00500 00000 020m ”350550005 0000< _00500 0000,0023 8003 E05— ...ufiufim m0v— 30.5.5000» 50.50009 303.5000» 50.50.0055 50500 3005540 8.503 m 030,—. 204 5050055030 50500505 00 5000—00 05055005 000 00550000055 00550000000: 555050505005m €37.55 50500505050350 550 55050000 500055 5055005 555000502 55050000 0000400 05055005 055500050: $3: 50502 50500w0055 5005000, 00 5000—00 300355005 50 000 50505505 0505055005 5050005005. 5050050000 550 550000055 550000055 50003050m 5050050505050 5550000055 5550000055 500505050035m AmomAHS 50500355 $33 055003; 5000500505 55050000 000050 5050050055 500500> ”55050050 0000000 8000005325 0% 00585 _.02 00050.50 5505005 5555 0>05 5555 050 .50 0000555 00500 050 5053 50503055 50035005 00 5000—00 05355005 5 00550000055 500505050035m 50500w055 50035005 8 5000—00 505005055 0555000005: 5005085005335 Amomné 300055000 5 350550000 000050 50035005 .50 50065 550550050 0002 5050050055 5003500m C 33 5050005055 305000005: 5550505005500 5005005555 505005055 5005000, 5 0050550090 0003.. 5m .5 05005 05u5v 00 5000—00 050055000 000 555000005: 0055500055 5005050505035“— 0550505500 mmm 50050850550 550 0550550050 000050 505005055 500500> 350550050 0000< 05 50500355 500500> $3: 0905 A0505: 0050500>0w 50500055 00 505500 05355005 5 0055500055 5550505050050 550 350550050 00000 .50 5050000055 9555 0050500>0w 50500500 00 5000—00 0500055005 5 0955500055 500508505>5m $58 0050500>0w 50500500 00 5000500 555000005: 505008505035m 90:15 383 00050Q 0500055000 5 350550000 000050 005050 005050260 550550000 00mm< 05055005 555090502 0% .0035 0550—5505 $555,550! 30.5.5000» 050550.50: 30.5.5000, 050550.505:— 0500500 30050555 50.5.80 0 030.0 205 0000808000 00 0000—00 3030000 mm 36006000 0000< 0.658% 0 _ F5 00000000000 00 000000 3020030 .0004 ”000800000 mo E0005 0000050 236.00 mm 0008000000 .00 000000000 0.; 00000000000 ”8000000000 .«0 000000000 3 0000000000 @003 05:00 0MB b02500 mm b58500: 00:3 £00 00000 00000000000 00000000.: SENS 002000020.— 8003 0302 00 000080>0w 3000200 00000005 0000000>0w _000020M b03300: 300800030m 00:00.003m 0% 000.. 00509002 sans 03.330003 00 0000—00 00.0335 3000? A30: 3030000 mm has—E0000 0003‘ 00000—000005 bBEoomm 00mw< $0003 030080030 0000 H 0% 00050002 000 _000000 202000 00 0000—00 3030000 0 580030 E008000>0m 000 300000 03308 00 0000—00 b0>00w00 mm @2023 3008000>0m SENS 0000—000 $600.0 00.0 000 _000000 0.0208 00 000200 5000000000 ~80000000$0m $000000 00000506 b03830 38—50000 .0000 30530 $000000 0098 0.0202 ”Emomfiam 00mm< 20208 .00 003 A803 000300202 00_0§00w00 300000 00 000200 303500 0.8 300000000 000030090 500000000 .800800030m AVFHE :00: Spam 3008000300 000 bmommoam 0000< 3000.5 .«0 0000 56.50000 00mm< 0003000 00.00.00.002 0% 000002 08002 095.5% >0! 303025» 00000002— €0.00t0> 0000000005 080000 3.8005. 8.0.80 _ 03.0. 206 0308 3000000 00.03 0000000000 00 0000—00 b0>00m00 00 3000000000 300000005 wE00000000 0003 0000000000 00 0000000 30000030 00 500000000 0000.0 00000000000 000.0000 00 0000—00 30>00w00 00 300000000 0000.0 000000 Egon 000000000000 0w0000xm 5000000000 _0003000m 5000000000 30000000000.”— 500000000 0000< swing 8030008 _0000000 00 .00—002 00%: 00000N 0% 00000 00000 000.000.0060 8 0000—00 b30000 00 0000000000 300000000>0m 00000 0000000000 $000000. 000 000800—050 00 0000.00 b30000 00 500000000 0000< 0000 0000000000 0000 00 000 0000 00m 0000000000 0000000000. 500000000 3000000000050 500000000 0000< AVNNHS 0020000200 00000000000000.3002 0.00: 0808. 0 .3080 00:00 0000003000 00000000000 00 0000—00 300000000 00 0000000000 .00 000000000 00; 030000200 .00 0&0»: 00 0000.00 b30000 00 300000000 0000< 00080000000 .00 000000000 0.0 00 0000—00 30000030 00 300000000 0000< 00000300000 .00 000000000 000 00 0000.00 30000030 00 0000000 0>00000000 000003.000 _03000000 020000300 .00 0300.0 000000000000 .00 000000000 00.0003 300 C 003000 00.0050 0000 @0300; 00005000 05030000.? 0000000000— 00000000 3020.2. 0.0080 0 0300. 207 00000000 00.0 000 000 000000 00.0 00000300000 0000000 802020 22.0 00 003080 0000000000 0000000 00:00 00000000 00005 000000 00000000 0003 000 00000 0003 00000800000 000000000 500000000 0000< 0000000000 030 bt0000m ”00000000005— .00 000000000 0.000000m 9000000000 000040. sans 00082002 0000000005 0080 2303 0 000: 09:30 00000000 .00 000 000 00 000000 30000000 003 0000000000 000000000m 00000000 00 000 000 00 00000 $30000 00 3000000000 300000000025 00000000 .00 000 000 00 0000—00 0.0>00w00 00 0000000000 0000< 0000300000 .0003000m 00000000500 5000000000 3000000000000 _0000000 00000> 000002 0000000000 .000< 0.0000 000 0830 00000> 00000—0 .00 00 D 0000: 8:00.00 0 0803000 00000003000 00000000000 00 0000.00 >_0>00000 00 0900000000 0000< 300000000 _00000000030‘0 000000w0000 _0000000000 50000000m 0000< sons 088:2 000000 802 0 02.00 000000000000 00.000 00 000000 30000000 00 00000000 000000 00>0 _000000 000000m 0000000 000000000 000— 0000 00000000 00000 0005 003000000 0000000000000 00 0w0w00 00 300—0 000_ 000 000000 000000000 0030.— 000000000 0000000000000 00>0 _000000 ”0000000009 Sans 008802 0000000005 800: 000005 0% 00>000 00000000 00v— 30300000» 0000000000 30300000» 0000000000— 0000000 302000. 00.0080 0 030.0 208 0000000000 000000000 00 0000—00 b0>00m00 00 33000000 _000000 000000xm 000000000000 0.0200000 00 0000000 00000000 000000000 0000000000000 00 0000000000 30000000350 00000000000 0.000000%.“ 0003000000 000000000 0000000000000 0.0000000 00 00 0000000 b0>00w00 00 0000000000000 0.0000000 000000000 00000 0000000000— 3608 00000000000 0.0800000 ”0000000000 3000000350 G _ Nu0v 00000000200 00000—0w0000m 00 0000—00 3300000 00 0000000000 53000000 000000 0000000000000 0% 000000030 000000000 00000 0000000000 00000000000 0.0000000: 000000000000 0.0000000 0900.505 000000006 00000000w0 w0000000 0 00 0000000 00 0000000000 00000000 0000000 000000030 w0000 0300000000 .00 00000000 000 w0000000 00000> 00000000 :03 0000000000000 .00 000000. 0000000000 .00 30300000 000000000 .00 0005 00000000000 .00 000.00 0000000003 ”00000000 00 00 0000—00 £30000 00 030—00008 000005 ”0000000000 30000000. Ann—"5 300-3000— Amoomv 00000000.,” 000 .00 00000000 00 000000m 000000000000 .00 0000:. 5000000000 300000000 30—00000. .0 w000000m 0.0 M00005 000000000000 00000 00 0000—00 300000000 00 0000000000 3000000030....— 00000000000 0000000000 000000000300 00000 00 0000—00 0.000000 00 500000000 08¢. 00 0000000000 0000000000300 300.0000 .00 03004 300000000 Amho0n0v 00000000200 $00: 000 00000000 00000 ,00 0000000000 00000000000 0000< ”000003000 _00000> 0000000030 000.0: 0% 000m 0§00E mov— 30200000» 0000000009 30300000, 0000000000— 0000000 300500.. 90.0003 0 030,—. 209 $000000 03000 00 000000 30000030 000 2000000000 00 0000000 3030000 00 3000—00, 00003—000000 0000000 w0000000 03000 000 00000000000 00 0000.00 30>00w00 00 00000 00 300.305— 0000 0000000 0000000000000 3000000000 0000000000200 00000> 00000000000 "00000000m 0000< Gauge 0000000000000 0000000005 0803 000000000 0 .5000 .0000? .0000000000m 000 00000 00 000 000 00 0000000 000000030 00 0000000000 00003—000000 000 00000000300 .00 0000000000 000. 00000000 300000000 00 000 000 00 0000000 00030030 00 0000800000 00003—000000 000 000000008 .00 000000000 000. 00000000 0300000000 00 000 00.0 00 0000—00 3030000 00 0000000000 0000000000: 000 55800000 _000w2000000 .00 000000000 00H 000 00000 .00 003 30800000 00000000000000 0 0000000>0 0000000003 00000000 00003—000000 5000000000 0000000000200 8008 .00 000 000 00 0000000 30500000 00000000 0 00300000, 000000 000005 0% 000,003 00 3000000000 00030—000090 300000000 00 003 5000000000 3000000000000 801M000 0000002 600002 00000005 $000.00 000— 30—000000» 000000009 30.0.0000» 00000WA000— 0000000 |€0000=< 3.0003 g 030,—. 210 0000000 00 0000000020 0000000 00 000000 30000030 00 0000800000 0000000000300 0000000300 0000000 0000000 00 0000000 30000000 00 300000000 00000 00>0m 0000000 >0 000000000000 000000m 0000>0000 0000000 00 000000 0000008 00000000 00 300000000 00000 00>0m 0000000 .00 0000000000 00050 0000000 .00 0000000000 00 0000—00 0000,0030 00 0000000000 0000000030 50000 0000000 300000000 00 0000000000 00000 00 0000000 000000 00000000000000 5000000000 $00 0 "5 00000000200 300: 00000000 00 000000000 00000 00>0m 0000000 .00 0000000000 0000000030 ”00000003 0000< 0000000030 020$ 0% 0.03m 0000000008 0000000000 =000>0 00 0000—00 00000030 00 b58008: 00000000000000 0000000 00000 .00 00000> 00000000 00 0000000 0000000 3030000 00 000000000 00000 00>0m _0000 00 0000000, 00000000 000000000000 w000000000 00026 00 000000 00000000000000 00030000 00 000000000 00000 0000mm 0000000000 00005 0000000000 0000000000300 0 0000000000 0000< 000 0000000 00 0.00 00 000000 5000000000 00000000000000 A 0 0 0 ”00 0000000000000 3000000000 00 000000000 00000 0000mm 000 0000000 .00 005 “b0000000m 0000< 00000-000A0m $003 083m 0w000000 .00! 303005» 0000003: 30.0.0.0; 0000000000— 0000000 30000000 €0.33 0 030,0 211 00000000 >00 00 00000 0000,00 5000000000 02028080 08 0829, 08 song Ea: 0000000000 00000000 .00 0000000000 >00 00 0002 b00000o03 0000000000000 000000000 300000000 0000 3 0% 000003 0000000000 000 m00>00 00 0000— 0000000000 00000000 0000000 000000 0000000000 00300 00 00000 0000000 000 000000060 0000 000000000 000w0m 085088 00000: Sons 000: 00 0000— 3000000000 000000> 00000000 00.00-0002 3000000000 0000000000300 0000000000 00.00-0002 0000 3 0% 000003 0000000000 30009» 00 0000000 3030000 00 5000000000 000000m 0000000000 00000000 00 0000000 >_0>00w00 00 b50033 0300000000 330.85 0800200000 5000000000 000000m 0000000000 000000> 00 0000000 5000000000 0300000000 Awomnfi $00: >00>00w00 00 b00300o00 >000000 0000000000 000E0> ”500800000 b00000 000000000 30.00-0002 00000N 0% 0.00000w 0002088 0005 9 0.302 0.083 3%: >_0>00w00 00 b58035 00003000m 0000000000 00>0m 020$ 0% 083m 0500..— >0! 30.000000; 00000000: 30.0.0000» 0000000005 00000000 30000000 00.0080 0 2000 212 300000030 00 0000—00 >_0>00w00 00 >00000000 00000000; >0000000 0000000000 00 500000000 .82 555525 08,0032. 0 500000000 0000< ”3000000000 0000000000300 00 300000000 0000< $000030 0000000000. M0000800 0803200 00000000000 9 0000.00 0000000 ”5000000000 0000080000000 GENE 00000000 8003 >_0>00w00 00 500000000 0000< 00000000 000000005 500000000 00004 .00 00000000000 000m 0% 0000003 00000000 200 00 >0008000 00000 0003 00000000000 000 00 00000— 000 0003 000000000 0000000000 0082.02 00 080093 0000000000 00000000000 03000000000 00 0000.00 >_0>00w00 00 500000000 .00 00000— 00 500000000 AmeHE 000000000000 :00: 00000 0000000000 000 000000000002 0000000000 0000000000000 .0090 500000000 0000< 00:00.00>0m 0000000 0% 00003 05:8 0000 200M005 00 00000000 00 0000—00 w00000 >00>00000 00 5000000000 0000000030 0000 00003000 00 0000005 >0000000000 0000000000 Awmmufi 00300000000000 00000000000000 00300000000000 00000000000000 0000000 003 0000000000000 00? 0000000000000 b00800000 00000> 0000000000 300: 0000000 >0006000 0000< 0000000000002 _00030000 500000000 0000< 000003000 .00 00 D 00000000~ 0% 00003 100000000 >0v~ 30.00000; 000000009 30.000000» 0000000000:— 00000000 30000000 00.0.80 0 0.000 213 00000000300 ammué 3300000200 00000030030000 8 000200 0000000001 0900800000 30203000300008 00 Anon: gnu—00> 30300000 00 503000000 00mm< 02803376000 1000300030 50050000 00wm< 0000000>ow 30000230 0% 0003 3000000000 00 000200 303080 0100000000 00000000000 30.0008 89m: 0000 030000000000 00000 .00 0000000000 o=0m 0% 000023 mwfiufim m0: 43030005» 0000000009 430300000» 000.000.00.00: 0000000 63005.30 3.0003 g 050k. 214 Table 2 Network Categories and Examples of Research Network Category Function Examples of Research Vertical networks Maximize the productivity of Wathne and Heide (2004) serially dependent functions by Wuyts, Stremersch, Van Den Bulte, creating partnerships among and F ranses (2004) independent skill-specialized J oshi and Campbell (2003) Internal networks Intermarket network Opportunity network firms Designed to reduce hierarchy and open fums to their environments Seek to leverage horizontal synergies across industries Organized around customer needs and market opportunities and designed to search for the best solutions Wathne, Biong, and Heide (2001) Kale, Singh, and Perlmutter (2000) Day (1994) J aworski and Kohli (1993) Kohli and Jaworski (1990) Dyer (1996a) Dyer (1996b) Dyer and Nobeoka (2000) Frels, Shervani, and Srivastava (2003) McEvily and Zaheer (1999) Rindfleisch and Moorman (2001) 215 000000000000 0000000 000 00000 00003000 CLUE 100000300000 05 E 5:00.000 000003002000— b=000000 0000030 0300.65 3ng =0m €280 00282022 050000 0.000580 0.00 an": .8020 @800 30030 000300000 00 0.000 b30030: 5000000000 00000002 02 mmanfi 00000000 0% 2300000: 000.0000 $000.0 080E 3000000000 00 200000005 5000000000 050000-000E goo—00000 .000 0000210. .00000—00m 00008200 80000300 x 3:00.000 0.00300 Z $500200 00000w030 000000000000 00000000 00000000 x b00000 0.003002 $020008 Am 0 NUS 0020000200 A _ SS .3050 0000 30—00000 0103002 00000000000000 00000000 3003002 00000000 0.00300 Z 00:00.000m0m 000000,,0 0% 0000400 00900 0000006000 00 0000—00 3005030 00 0000 00000000 0000 0000 0000000 .00 0000000005 3900 0000006000 00 0000200 b02080 00 0000 000000000 00900 000005000 00 .0000 000000000 .00 000000 Z Awomué 0000000 30300000 00 0000 00005 00900 00005000 ”0000 0000000 .00 0020002 003000: 0300000239 888 0:02 0gmufim30000000000m mov— 3030000> 0000000000: 303000000» 0000000000000— 0000000 3000003 8:030 08000050 008.? 0.8502 m 030% 216 30—00000 9 0000—00 30300000 @020 0500200 000 0w0000 00300 000 .0w000>00 090000 003000 M0w000>00 0% 000000m 0:00.00 60000300000005 30.000000 00002 00000005000005 Ace—H00 0900: .00—030x00a awe—000000 E 0w0000 0 mike—3.0 53% 05 058008 08308 815 8%: 0005 00000000 00000000 ram 00300 090—00000 000003000 00 003000 30.5 0% 0000003005 00300 .00 0000000000 00 000000008 000000000 Amnué 335 0000.00 30200000 0102000000 00300000 ,00 003 ”0030.0 500000000 .00—003000 00 0030.00 000000—005 0% 008m 000003000 0000000000000 v00 30: 00003 00 00000—000 00 i b00003 1000000000030 SENS 00000—00 30300000 00 b=000000 00003.00— 0800 0000005 500000000 80003000 5 00002.05 A33: 008m 00200000000000 0&000000 000000.000 .000 _000000 000 00030000 800w000 0002. «0000000000 00802 a 88:03 03800 Gsus :00: 0000: 00000000090 1000000 00003.00— >0=00000U 00.003000 3000,000— 0000003 0% 0.8m mwfiuskmcosfionoi ~13. Amvofimtw> 0000:0000”. #0003020; Emacoqoufi 0030000 Wrap—03‘ €00.80 0 030,0 217 00008000 000050 00 0000—00 3030000 00 05003000 0 5 0000005 05 000000m 00008000 000050 00 0000—00 30300000 00 0000 00000 005.. 00000000 .00 0000002 0.003000 05 0000000000 B 0000.0 0003000 0000005 000050 00 0000000 30300000 00000 00000 00050 0000000 Aoovwné $00 5 00 0000050 0000 00 0000002 000000000 00005< ”0000050 0000 00 0000002 000000000 00005< 200900 0% 00030 000000.000 000050 00 0000—00 20300000 00 000.5 030 0003000 500 05 0000005 00000000 000050 00 0000—00 30005000 00 0000 b00065: 0000000 .00 0000000 05 0090— 05 0000 00005 00000 .00 0000002 000000000 00000.0 030 000050 00 0000—00 50300000 0003000 0000005 ”0000 00005 Aoovmufi 00 0000050 0000 00 0000002 000000000 00005< 00000050 0000 00 0000002 000000000 00005< 330: 00.00 unfit—05000500000.— »02 30300000» 000000m0n— 30300000» 0000000000— 0000000 RES—0000 5.0008 m 030B 218 000000000 00020005000 000000 00 E500 05 00000005 35000000 0< 000000000 0002005000000 000088 2 00050 20 000000000 90000 0103000 m< 00000500 000_0:0x00m 35000000 5600a QGHE 000005< :00: 0003600 005 #000000 w0000000_ 000000000 0 00 0000—00 b0>00m00 00 0050 000 000.000 055000000 000>0 b00005 3000000000 000000000 0 00 0000—00 30300000 SQHE 005000 3003 000000005 0% 00 0050 000 000.000 095000000 30.000000 8 0m0000 55000000 000000000 8 0w0000 0050M 0035002 000000.000 000050 00 0000—00 30300000 00 500009 00008000 000050 5.03 000300 30300000 Sovmné 00 0103000 0 00 005000000 000000000 00005< @8000 55000000 000000000 00005< 8003 000500 50500500050000; N0! 30300000» 0000000009 30300000» 0000000000— 0000000 30000000 00.0080 0 030.0 219 $000000 00000000300 00 0000000000000 00 0000—00 30300000 00 0000 .00 0000035 03000000 000000—98 00 0000000000000 00 0000—00 b0>000w00 00 0000 .00 b0000Q 00.003000 00000 00 000000» 000 0000 M0005 mafia—05000500000.— >0! 300005 00000000000000 _00000000m >0000Q 30300000, 000000009 303000000» 0000000000— 000n=000000=0< 0000000 000000 00005—0000 0% 000000m . 3305 300.000. 00.0080 0 0300 220 Table 4 Pre-Test Results of Transaction Cost Economics and Control Variables TCE Variable Treatment Mean N t-value p-value Buyer Asset Specificity High 5.67 18 6.27 < .001 Low 2.94 Buyer Performance Ambiguity High 5.28 18 6.06 < .001 Low 3.39 Buyer Demand Uncertainty High 5.83 18 13.97 < .001 Low 3.11 Buyer Technological Uncertainty High 6.00 18 9.95 < .001 Low 3.1 1 Control Variable Market Position High 5.33 18 0.22 NS Low 5.22 Number of Suppliers High 3.67 18 -12.47 < .001 Low 6.33 Qualified Suppliers in market High 3.5 16* -7.30 < .001 Low 5.50 Purchase Frequency High 4.39 18 3.06 < .01 Low 3.22 * Two returned surveys had missing data 221 mo. V no.0 S o 5 304 0000050 000000000 8. v mZ 03.0 005 08.0 S o 0 M: :wi 302 00555 _o. v 36 E o v 30: b00009 0.003002 8. v mz 2&0- Rao 03 .o E o 5 m0 005 005005 0000mm 05007: 00:30 0002 00.0.10 00555 5000000— 00550@ 2 0000000005. 0300000» 020.»..— 00000@ 0000000 00000000— 3070 0000 0000.0 -50 .53 0000059 00000000 035000000 000000000 30 Z 005505 .000 30000: 500300 Z 0055.5 00025 .00 00.000“ 0009.000— m 030,—. 222 00 00 Z a 0. : 0 E 00 E 00 00800 00000 0000505 N00 ._00 0000000000005 00>0m 33 t 2 n : 0 2 0 E 00 2 00 00080 .0005 030302 N00 . ~00 00000000000.“ 00>0m nwi N t 00 00 z 0 0 0 2 00 0 00 .0050 00 08 00000080 000 .000 033 00>0m 33 om 00 00 2 0 0 a : 00 2 00 000000 .00 000 00000800 000 .000 003. 0000mm 35 00 om 00 0 0 : 0 E 0.0 00 00 000050 0:000 000000200 000 .000 033. 00>0m 33 2 00 00 2 0 n 2 2 00 : 00.. 000050 0200 00200800 000 .000 03.2 000:0 00000 0 0050002 00w0002 com A 8.0. v awn Eh can 0mm 0.05 0.0.00...— Z 00080005. 0000500»: 0000000000. 0000000930 -002 00000 000.5 00000 0000. £5 800080 08030000 6000 00.2600 00080 00.005 000.003 08500 00 00000075 0000 0:00 00300000000000 03.0.5 0 030,—. 223 : 2 00 : 0 0 2 E 00 S 00 0000080 0000302 ooflagotom 00>0m 33 2 t 00 N0 0 0 0 2 00 : 00 000080 000055. 00000000000005 00>0m :33 m 2 2 00 0 m 0 3 N0 2 t 00 0080 0:000 00000800 00: .000 0 080028080 00%0m 33 om 2 00 0 0 0 : 00 00 2 00 0:800 0:000 00000800 000 0 .000 0 0800280080 00>0m awe v 00 2 00 E 2 0: 0 a a 0 00 00080 8:000 00000800 002 .080 000800 00>0m 33 00 2 R o 0 2 00 : 00 2 00 00800 8:00 000000800 002 .002 000800 00>0m Ami m human-02 hum—~02 écm A :cm V cam era Gen 9mm 202 2050“ Z «awn—0000B. 8852:: afloaaaOLP ammo—32:: -00Z 00000 00000 00000 30.0 no: 50080 080200.00 6000 0002.000 000000 00.003 00.003 08300 .00 00000075 0000 0:00 00.0080 0 0.000 224 on em on on 2 _N mm an no mm cyanogen _mm mmm _mm m2 3 S: w: om. 9mm wE vow flfloh E 8 mm 2 w o o 2 mm 2 cm 5:280 533.85 wagon hob—m 33 : 2 2 : m m o S on 2 on $380 353.85 28809 Baum awmm o how—332 Susan—z 3m A com v can 2% can cmm 2:5 «Baum Z 2.253.; 885cm»: 23:53.; £853»: .32 ._.—EU .__—9.0 9.30 £5 25 52.8.— Asaoaam Gav $22: :25 55;» 55$» 823% a: 3:836 «NE 8.5— 8.233 e asap. 225 93 mod 3 £550 33 3:253 “oz 83 £2 85 on 83 £2.89 awe bmawmns oogotom “exam 304 $3 2 .o 3 £350 33 3:895 .oz 22 mus Ono- 8 $3 5:35 :9: bmswfig oogofiom 53m .35 m 2: 2+ on 93:85 Hommofifiooh Hob—m 33 3:395 “oz 22 52 one on 3.3 - @5858: _mofio—oqnooh Baum :3: v a: w? on 35.28:: @885 83m 33 8:253 N85 32 e .m on _86 - 358.85 9385 Exam 3: m 83 an on bsmssa ooaafiotom 5&5 33 graham 23 82 NS. 9.. mod - €5.35 Baotou 53m .3: N 83 E .v S $2.283 ~82 ism 33 Brenna ”8d 82 a: S 32 - éofioam .83 5&5 $5 _ mononucmwfl o=_a>-n 5:539 532 2 82525» .3 gnu—5.3.; anofiguouflguc 5953— «@389»: .2: 325.6 FEE—Sm baa—Em ..8 .__—9.0 5.308% 39,—. 99:261— 5539 5525.350 _aouuo>-m==mo~— b oEaH 226 $3 a: om £85 33 8:89: :oz 83 «a: 8.~ cm 83 £23 AME bmofiooqm 83¢. “935 304 :2 Ed 8 £25 33 8:253 .oz 33 9%: OZ 2 E: 5:89 fiE $0502; :83 Liam 3: £ 23 of mm £380 33 8:233 82 $3 83 v: R ~85 £3.00 .35 bmommooam Bmm< Sham Bo:— wmfl :1 x £380 33 8:89: 82 NS .o 33 3m x and £2.80 in 36:33 .82 2.5 E: a: 82 Ed on $380 33 8:3:3 $3 cam ”Nd- on $3 £380 :3: bESBoGD 9880a huhflm 33 33 one on $350 33 8:39: 82 83 53 :.o S. 82 9:380 :3: Eggs: 89:5 :35 .3: o 335.33g 2:57: nouagon :32 2 82.3.2; .3 32:39:. «no—5:35 9.9.0 5953— ammo—32:: ._8 223.5 FEE—Sm .6533”— .Su 95.5 fluhaomom «8H. n.o=o>o‘u 55MB APuuouv 5 «fish. 227 of .m :3 _m :58: 33 8:895 82 Ed 83 8.: 8. 83 :58: 8.888: :3: _momwofifiooh 855 33 85 m _ .N 2 E58: 33 8:885 Sod 2 _.N 8.: mm 5 _ no :58: 5:888: :9: 8829889 8?: 8:: a: 82 52 E :58: 33 8:885 :8: 58a :2 mm 2 _.o :58: swam 558.625 98809 .555 33 55: 8a 8 :58: 33 8:895 82 E _ .o 8 _ .N 8.: _.m 83 :58: :9: 8888: :88: 85:: 8:: :2 82 of 2 :58: so: 8:895 82 88 83 5.: 8 mad 858: nwmm bEwSE< 0:58:38: Exam 3:: 82 o: R :58: 33 8:895 82 w _ no 8: .N 52 8 853 858: :3: 883:2 88808: 8.3: 8:: 8 33549;: 2:5»-.— 53859 :32 Z .823?!» a: 2.25.3.5. «nufiuaohhdguv 5953— 885:9?— .8._ ton—95 FEE—Sm baa-._.”: .3.— 93.5 auuaumom «nah Ranged 553) 6.88: 9 2:89 228 8 «N _ 2 3:8: 3:: 8N: 8:.N N 8 8 o : 3:8: 8:: 383:2 . oogotom Exam 33 8 MN _ N: 3:8: 33 8:89: 82 :8: :8: N 8 :N o 2 3:8: :8: 388:2 Nu: can :5 ouggotom 83:: 8:: N8 :8 :8 8 ON 8 2 3:8: :6: 8a.: :8: N 8 8 _ m 3:8: 8:: 38:82:: 884 BEE 33 N8 NN N N: 3:8: 33 8:89: :8: 8:: N 8 8 c m 3:8: 8:: 3888: N8 :8 :8 8:4 83: 8:: N8 :8 :8 8 8 o _ 38:8: 33 :8: N83. _ 8 :N o a 38:80 :8: 38:88: Homm< Exam 33 8 8 o N 38:80 3:: 8:89.: :3 :8: N 8 «N N 2 3:88: 8:: 3888: 3:8 3 8:3 83:: 8:: N8 :8 3 8852:: «_._—3-: onus—um a: .83. hum—:95 312:8:— uozn—nsm 2.253;. 2253:. 8352:: :8 98:95 ._.—O «not—.0 335.:— Boz macaw 555) 95.5 5950mm 8:88: :8: a :5: 2:550 3:25 355050-333— w 035,—. 229 on _m o m 53:03 33 wwod mood _ on mm o ~ 3689 awe b55583 3333503. Sham Boa em 8 _ 2 £35 33 Brenna 83 on; N on 2 o m $8.5 in 98:85 mm: as E: 3236289 93 :3: mg: Ba 3: on x _ ~ ~ £28 33 086 mood m cm mm o m 3655 awmm b35583 vague Sham 33 cm mm o 2 bacon 33 Bcogqam ago 3: _ on a o w £83 35 9328:: N2: 98 :5— vacuum 59m =me 3: 93 E: mono—_.cmhl o=_a>-m 228m .3 13¢... 3:955 #358:— uozmmsm 3253:. 23.53:. mononucnh—w ._8 «noun—am -_._U 23.:an 333...— 262 9.20 5539 $3.5 50250: 5.583— 55 a .53 2.5280 8.283 a «ES 230 REFERENCES 231 REFERENCES Achrol, Ravi S. (1997), "Changes in the Theory of Interorganizational Relations in Marketing: Toward a Network Paradigm," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 25 (1), 56-71. ---- (1991), "Evolution of the Marketing Organization: New Forms for Turbulent Environments," Journal of Marketing, 55 (4), 77-93. Achrol, Ravi S. and Gregory T. Gundlach (1999), "Legal and Social Safeguards Against Opportunism in Exchange," Journal of Retailing, 75 (1), 107-124. Achrol, Ravi S. and Philip Kotler (1999), "Marketing in the Network Economy, " Journal of Marketing, 63 (Special Issue), 146-163. Adler, Paul S. and Seok-Woo Kwon (2002), "Social Capital: Prospects for a New Concept," The Academy of Management Review, 27 (1), 17-40. Adler, Terry R., Robert F. Scherer, Sidney L. Barton, and Ralph Katerberg (1998), "An Empirical Test of Transaction Cost Theory: Validating Contract Typology," Journal of Applied Management Studies, 7 (2), 185- 200. Ahuja, Gautarn (2000), "Collaboration Networks, Structural Holes, and Innovation: A Longitudinal Study," Administrative Science Quarterly, 45 (3), 425-455. Akerlof, George A. (1970), "The Market for Lemons: Quality, Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84 (3), 488-500. Andersen, Otto and Amt Buvik (2001), "Inter-Firm Co-Ordination: International versus Domestic Buyer-Seller Relationships," Omega, 29(2), 207-219. Anderson, Erin (1985), "The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee: A ' Transaction Cost Analysis," Marketing Science, 4 (3), 234-254. ---- (1988), "Transaction Costs as Determinants of Opportunism in Integrated and Independent Sales F orces," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9(3), 247-264. Anderson, Erin and Anne T. Coughlan (1987), " International Market Entry and Expansion via Independent or Integrated Channels of Distribution," Journal of Marketing, 51 (1), 71-82. 232 Anderson, Erin and David C. Schmittlein (1984), "Integration of the Sales Force: An Empirical Examination," The Rand Journal of Economics, 15 (3), 385- 395. Anderson, Erin and Barton Weitz (1992), "The Use of Pledges to Build and Sustain Commitment in Distribution Channels," Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (1), 18-34. Anderson, James C., Hakan Hakansson, and Jan Johanson (1994), "Dyadic Business Relationships Within a Business Network Context," Journal of Marketing, 58 (4), 1-15. Antia, Kersi D., Mark E. Bergen, Shantanu Dutta, and Robert J. Fisher (2006), "How Does Enforcement Deter Gray Market Incidence?" J oumal of Marketing, 70(1), 92-106. Antia, Kersi D. and Gary L. Frazier (2001), "The Severity of Contract Enforcement in Interfirm Channel Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 65 (4), 67-81. Artz, Kendall W. and Thomas Brush (2000), "Asset Specificity, Uncertainty and Relational Norms: An Examination of Coordination Costs in Collaborative Strategic Alliances," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 41 (4), 337-362. Aulakh, Preet S. and Masaaki Kotabe (1997), "Antecedents and Performance Implications of Channel Integration in Foreign Markets," Journal of International Business Studies, 28 (1), 145-175. Baker, Wayne E. (1990), "Market Networks and Corporate Behavior," The American Journal of Sociology, 96 (3), 589-625. Balakrishnan, Srinivasan and Birger Wemerfelt (1986), "Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration," Strategic Management Journal, 7 (4), 347-359. Barney, Jay E, Frances L. Edwards, and Al H. Ringleb (1992), "Organizational Responses to Legal Liability: Employee Exposure to Hazardous Materials, Vertical Integration, and Small Firm Production," The Academy of Management Journal, 35 (2), 328-349. Becker, Marshall H. (1970), "Sociometric Location and Innovativeness: Reformulation and Extension of the Diffusion Model," American Sociological Review, 35 (2), 267-282. 233 Beckman, Christine M., Pamela R. Haunschild, and Damon J. Phillips (2004), "Friends or Strangers? Firm-Specific Uncertainty, Market Uncertainty, and Network Partner Selection," Organization Science, 15 (3), 259-275. Bell, Geoffrey G. (2005), "Clusters, Networks, and Firm Innovativeness," Strategic Management Journal, 26 (3), 287-295. Bello, Daniel C. and David I. Gilliland (1997), "The Effect of Output Controls, Process Controls, and Flexibility on Export Channel Performance," Journal of Marketing, 61 (1), 22-38. Bello, Daniel C. and Rim Lohtia (1995), "Export Channel Design: The Use of Foreign Distributors and Agents," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 23 (2), 83-93. Bensaou, M. and Erin Anderson (1999), "Buyer-Supplier Relations in Industrial Markets: When Do Buyers Risk Making Idiosyncratic Investments?" Organization Science, 10 (4), 460-481. Bergen, Mark, Jan B. Heide, and Shantanu Dutta (1998), "Managing Gray Markets Through Tolerance of Violations: A Transaction Cost Perspective," Managerial and Decision Economics, 19(3), 157-165. Bergh, Donald D. and Michael W. Lawless (1998), "Portfolio Restructuring and Limits to Hierarchical Governance: The Effects of Environmental Uncertainty and Diversification Strategy," Organization Science, 9 (1), 87- 102. Boje, David M. and David A. Whetten (1981), "Effects of Organizational Strategies and Contextual Constraints on Centrality and Attributions of Influence in Interorganizational Networks," Administrative Science Quarterly, 26 (3), 378-395. Bradach, Jeffery and Robert G. Eccles (1989), "Price, Authority and Trust: From Ideal Types to Plural Forms," Annual Review of Sociology, 15, 97-118. Brass, Daniel J. (1984), "Being in the Right Place: A Structural Analysis of Individual Influence in an Organization," Administrative Science Quarterly, 29(4), 518-539. Brass, Daniel J. and Marlene E. Burkhardt (1992), "Centrality and Power in Organizations," in Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Action, Nitin Nohria and Robert G. Eccles, Eds. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 191-21 5. 234 ---- (1993), "Potential Power and Power Use: An Investigation of Structure and Behavior," The Academy of Management Journal, 36 (3), 441-470. Brouthers, Keith D. (2002), "Institutional, Cultural and Transaction Cost Influences on Entry Mode Choice and Performance," Journal of International Business Studies, 33 (2), 203-221. Brouthers, Keith D., Lance Eliot Brouthers, and Steve Werner (2003), "Transaction Cost-Enhanced Entry Mode Choices and Firm Performance," Strategic Management Journal, 24 (12), 1239-1248. Brown, James R., Chekitan S. Dev, and Dong-Jin Lee (2000), "Managing Marketing Channel Opportunism: The Efficacy of Alternative Governance Mechanisms," Journal of Marketing, 64 (2), 51-65. Bucklin, Louis P. and Sanjit Sengupta (1993), "Organizing Successful Co- Marketing Alliances," Journal of Marketing, 57 (2), 32-46. Burkhardt, Marlene E. and Daniel J. Brass (1990), "Changing Patterns of Patterns of Change: The Effects of a Change in Technology on Social Network Structure and Power," Administrative Science Quarterly, 35 (1), 104-127. Burt, Ronald S. (2000), "The Network Structure of Social Capital," in Research in Organizational Behaviour, Vol. 22: Elsevier Science Inc., 345-423. ---- (1992a), "The Social Structure of Competition," in Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Action, Nitin Nohria and R.G. Eccles, Eds. Boston, MA.: Harvard Business School Press, 57-91. ---- (1992b), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Buvik, Amt (1998), "The Effect of Manufacturing Technology on Purchase Contracts," International Journal of Purchasing and Materials Management, 34(4), 21-27. ---- (2000), "Is Vertical Co-Ordination an Effective Response to Economic and Technological Ties in Industrial Purchasing Relationships?" Journal of Business to Business Marketing, 7 (4), 69-92. Buvik, Amt and Otto Andersen (2002), "The Impact of Vertical Coordination on Ex Post Transaction Costs in Domestic and International Buyer-Seller Relationships," Journal of International Marketing, 10(1), 1-24. 235 Buvik, Amt and Kj ell Gronhaug (2000), "Inter-Firm Dependence, Environmental Uncertainty and Vertical Co-Ordination in Industrial Buyer-Seller Relationships," Omega, 28 (4), 445-454. Buvik, Amt and George John (2000), "When Does Vertical Coordination Improve Industrial Purchasing Relationships?" Journal of Marketing, 64 (4), 52-64. Buvik, Amt and Torger Reve (2001), "Asymmetrical Deployment of Specific Assets and Contractual Safeguarding in Industrial Purchasing Relationships," Journal of Business Research, 51 (2), 101-113. Campbell, Donald T. (1955), "The Informant in Quantitative Research," The American Journal of Sociology, 60 (4), 339-342. Cannon, Joseph P., Ravi S. Achrol, and Gregory T. Gundlach (2000), "Contracts, Norms, and Plural Form Governance," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 28 (2), 180-194. Cannon, Joseph P. and William D. Perreault, Jr. (1999), "Buyer-Seller Relationships in Business Markets," Journal of Marketing Research, 36 (4), 439-460. Celly, Kirti Sawhney, Robert E. Spekman, and John W. Kamauff (1999), "Technological Uncertainty, Buyer Preferences and Supplier Assurances: An Examination of Pacific Rim Purchasing Arrangements," J oumal of International Business Studies, 30(2), 297-316. Chiles, Todd H. and John F. McMackin (1996), "Integrating Variable Risk Preferences, Trust, and Transaction Cost Economics," The Academy of Management Review, 21 (1), 73-99. Coase, Ronald H. (1937), "The Nature of the Firm," Economica, 4 (16), 386-405. Coleman, James S. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ---- (1988), "Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital," The American Journal of Sociology, 94 (Supplement), 895-8120. Coles, J erilyn W. and William S. Hester1y(1998), "The Impact of F irm-Specific Assets and the Interaction of Uncertainty: An Examination of Make or Buy Decisions in Public and Private Hospitals," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 36 (3), 383-409. 236 Combs, James G. and David J. Ketchen, Jr. (1999), "Explaining Interfirrn Cooperation and Performance: Toward a Reconciliation of Predictions from the Resource-Based View and Organizational Economics," Strategic Management Journal, 20 (9), 867-888. Cook, Karen S. and Richard M. Emerson (1978), "Power, Equity and Commitment in Exchange Networks," American Sociological Review, 43 (5), 721-739. Cook, Karen S., Richard M. Emerson, and Mary R. Gillmore (1983), "The Distribution of Power in Exchange Networks: Theory and Experimental Results," The American Journal of Sociology, 89 (2), 275-305. Cook, Thomas D. and Donald T. Campbell (1979), Quasi-Experimentation: Design and Analysis Issues for Field Settings. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin. Cyert, Richard M. and James G. March (1992), A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (2nd ed.). Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishing. Dahlstrom, Robert and Ame Nygaard (1999), "An Empirical Investigation of Ex Post Transaction Costs in Franchised Distribution Channels," Journal of Marketing Research, 36 (2), 160-170. Dankowski, James A., George A. Barnett, and Matthew H. Friedland (1986), "Interorganizational Networks via Shared Public Relations Firms' Centrality, Diversification, Media Coverage, and Publics' Images," in Communication Yearbook, Vol. 10. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications, 808-830. David, Robert J. and Shin-Kap Han (2004), "A Systematic Assessment of the Empirical Support for Transaction Cost Economics," Strategic Management Journal, 25 (1), 39-58. Day, George S. (1994), "The Capabilities of Market-Driven Organizations," Journal of Marketing, 58 (4), 37-52. Delmas, Magali A. (1999), "Exposing Strategic Assets to Create New Competencies: The Case of Technological Acquisition in the Waste Management Industry in Europe and North America," Industrial and Corporate Change, 8 (4), 635-671. Dutta, Shantanu, Mark Bergen, Jan B. Heide, and George John (1995), "Understanding Dual Distribution: The Case of Reps and House Accounts," Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 11 (1), 189-204. 237 Dutta, Shantanu, Jan B. Heide, and Mark Bergen (1999), "Vertical Territorial Restrictions and Public Policy: Theories and Industry Evidence," Journal of Marketing, 63 (4), 121-134. Dutta, Shantanu and George John (1995), "Combining Lab Experiments and Industry Data in Transaction Cost Analysis: The Case of Competition as a Safeguard," Journal of Labor Economics and Organizations, 11 (1), 87- 111. Dyer, Jeffrey H. (1996a), "Does Governance Matter? Keiretsu Alliances and Asset Specificity as Sources of Japanese Competitive Advantage," Organization Science, 7 (6), 649-666. ---- (1997), "Effective Interfirrn Collaboration: How Firms Minimize Transaction Costs and Maximize Transaction Value," Strategic Management Journal, 18 (7), 535-556. ---- (1996b), "Specialized Supplier Networks as a Source of Competitive Advantage: Evidence from the Auto Industry," Strategic Management Journal, 17(4), 271-291. Dyer, Jeffrey H. and Wujin Chu (2003), "The Role of Trustworthiness in Reducing Transaction Costs and Improving Performance: Empirical Evidence from the United States, Japan, and Korea," Organization Science, 14(1), 57-68. Dyer, Jeffrey H. and Kentaro Nobeoka (2000), "Creating and Managing a High- Perforrnance Knowledge-Sharing Network: The Toyota Case," Strategic Management Joumal, 21 (3), 345-367. Eccles, R.G. (1981), "The Quasifirrn in the Construction Industry," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2 (4), 335-3 57. Erramilli, M. Krishna and C. P. Rao (1993), "Service Firms' International Entry- Mode Choice: A Modified Transaction-Cost Analysis Approach," Journal of Marketing, 57 (3), 19-38. F ein, Adam J. and Erin Anderson (1997), "Patterns of Credible Commitments: Territory and Brand Selectivity in Industry Distribution Channels," Journal of Marketing, 61 (2), 19-34. Folta, Timothy B. (1998), "Governance and Uncertainty: The Trade-off Between Administrative Control and Commitment," Strategic Management Journal, 19 (11), 1007-1028. 238 Forward, John, Rachelle Canter, and Ned Kirsch (1976), "Role-Enactment and Deception Methodologies: Alternative Paradigms?" American Psychologist, 31 (8), 595-604. Frazier, Gary L. and Walfried M. Lassar (1996), "Determinants of Distribution Intensity," Journal of Marketing, 60(4), 39-51. Freeman, Linton C. (1979), "Centrality in Social Networks Conceptual Clarification," Social Networks, 1 (3), 215-239. F rels, Judy K., Tasadduq Shervani, and Rajendra K. Srivastava (2003), "The Integrated Networks Model: Explaining Resource Allocations in Network Markets," Journal of Marketing, 67 (1), 29-45. Gadde, Lars-Erik and Lars-Gunnar Mattsson (1987), "Stability and Change in Network Relationships," International Journal of Research in Marketing, 4 (1), 29-41. Galaskiewicz, Joseph and Stanley Wasserman (1989), "Mimetic Processes Within an Interorganizational Field: An Empirical Test, " Administrative Science Quarterly, 34 (3), 454-479. Ganesan, Shankar (1994), "Determinants of Long-Term Orientation in Buyer- Seller Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 58 (2), 1-19. ---- (1993), "Negotiation Strategies and the Nature of Channel Relationships," Journal of Marketing Research, 30 (2), 183-203. Gatignon, Hubert and Erin Anderson (1988), "The Multinational Corporation's Degree of Control over Foreign Subsidiaries: An Empirical Test of a Transaction Cost Explanation," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4 (2), 305-336. Geller, Daniel M. (1978), "Involvement in Role-Playing Simulations: A Demonstration with Studies on Obedience," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36(3), 219-235. Geyskens, Inge, J an-Benedict E. M. Steenkamp, and Nirrnalya Kumar (2006), "Make, Buy, or Ally: A Transaction Cost Theory Meta-Analysis," The Academy of Management Journal, 49 (3), 519-543. Ghosh, Mrinal and George John (2005), "Strategic Fit in Industrial Alliances: An Empirical Test of Governance Value Analysis," J oumal of Marketing Research, 42 (3), 346-357. 239 Gimeno, Javier (2004), "Competition Within and Between Networks: The Contingent Effect of Competitive Embeddedness on Alliance Formation," The Academy of Management Journal, 47 (6), 820-840. Gnyawali, Devi R. and Ravindranath Madhavan (2001), "Cooperative Networks and Competitive Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective," The Academy of Management Review, 26 (3), 431-445. Granovetter, Mark S. (1985), "Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness," The American Journal of Sociology, 91 (3), 481-510. Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver Hart (1986), "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691-719. Gulati, Ranjay (1998), "Alliances and Networks," Strategic Management Journal, 19(4), 293-317. ---- (1995a), "Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances," The Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 85-112. ---- (1999), "Network Location and Learning: The Influence of Network Resources and Firm Capabilities on Alliance Formation," Strategic Management Journal, 20(5), 397-420. ---- (1995b), "Social Structure and Alliance Formation Patterns: A Longitudinal Analysis," Administrative Science Quarterly, 40 (4), 619-652. Gulati, Ranjay and Martin Gargiulo (1999), "Where Do Interorganizational Networks Come From?" The American Journal of Sociology, 104 (5), 1439-1493. Gulati, Ranjay, Paul R. Lawrence, and Phanish Puranam (2005), "Adaptation in Vertical Relationships: Beyond Incentive Conflict," Strategic Management Journal, 26 (5), 415-440. Hakansson, Hakan and Ivan Snehota (1995), Developing Relationships in Business Networks. New York: Routledge. Hansen, Morten T. (1999), "The Search-Transfer Problem: The Role of Weak Ties in Sharing Knowledge Across Organization Subunits," Administrative Science Quarterly, 44 (1), 82-111. 240 Heide, Jan B. (1994), "Interorganizational Governance in Marketing Channels," Journal of Marketing, 58 (1), 71-85. ---- (2003), "Plural Governance in Industrial Purchasing," Journal of Marketing, 67 (4), 18-29. Heide, Jan B., Shantanu Dutta, and Mark Bergen (1998), "Exclusive Dealing and Business Efficiency: Evidence from Industry Practice," Journal of Law and Economics, 41 (2), 387-407. Heide, Jan B. and George John (1990), "Alliances in Industrial Purchasing: The Determinants of Joint Action in Buyer-Seller Relationships," Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (1), 24-36. ---- (1992), "Do Norms Matter in Marketing Relationships?" Journal of Marketing, 56(2), 32-44. ---- (1988), "The Role of Dependence Balancing In Safeguarding Transaction- Specific Assets in Conventional Channels," Journal of Marketing, 52 (l ), 20-35. Heide, Jan B. and Anne S. Miner (1992), "The Shadow of the Future: Effects of Anticipated Interaction and Frequency of Contact on Buyer-Seller Cooperation," The Academy of Management Journal, 35 (2), 265-291. Heide, Jan B. and Rodney L. Stump (1995), "Performance Implications of Buyer- Supplier Relationships in Industrial Markets: A Transaction Cost Explanation," J oumal of Business Research, 32 (1), 57-66. Houston, Mark B. and Shane A. Johnson (2000), "Buyer-Supplier Contracts Versus Joint Ventures: Determinants and Consequences of Transaction Structure," Journal of Marketing Research, 37 (l ), 1-15. Iacobucci, Dawn (1996), Networks in Marketing. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Iacobucci, Dawn and Nigel Hopkins (1992), "Modeling Dyadic Interactions and Networks in Marketing," Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (1), 5-17. lngham, Hilary and Steve Thompson (1994), "Wholly-Owned vs. Collaborative Ventures for Diversifying Financial Services," Strategic Management Journal, 15 (4), 325-334. Jackson Jr., Donald W., Janet E. Keith, and Richard K. Burdick (1984), "Purchasing Agents' Perceptions of Industrial Buying Center Influence: A Situational Approach," Journal of Marketing, 48 (4), 75-83. 241 J ap, Sandy D. (2001), "Perspectives on Joint Competitive Advantages in Buyer- Supplier Relationships," International Journal of Research in Marketing, 18 (1/2), 19-35. J ap, Sandy D. and Erin Anderson (2003), "Safeguarding Interorganizational Performance and Continuity Under Ex Post Opportunism," Management Science, 49 (12), 1684-1701. J ap, Sandy D. and Shankar Ganesan (2000), "Control Mechanisms and the Relationship Life Cycle: Implications for Safeguarding Specific Investments and Developing Commitment," J oumal of Marketing Research, 37 (2), 227-245. J aworski, Bernard J. and Ajay K. Kohli (1993), "Market Orientation: Antecedents and Consequences," Journal of Marketing, 57 (3), 53-70. John, George (1984), "An Empirical Investigation of Some Antecedents of Opportunism in a Marketing Channel," Journal of Marketing Research, 21 (3), 278-289. John, George and Torger Reve (1982), "The Reliability and Validity of Key Informant Data from Dyadic Relationships in Marketing Channels," Journal of Marketing Research, 19 (4), 517-524. John, George and Barton Weitz (1989), "Salesforce Compensation: An Empirical Investigation Of Factors Related to Use of Salary Versus Incentive Compensation," Journal of Marketing Research, 26 (1), 1-14. John, George and Barton A. Weitz (1988), "Forward Integration into Distribution: An Empirical Test of Transaction Cost Analysis," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4 (2), 337-355. Jones, Candace, William S. Hesterly, and Stephen P. Borgatti (1997), "A General Theory of Network Governance: Exchange Conditions and Social Mechanisms," The Academy of Management Review, 22 (4), 911-945. Joshi, Ashwin W. and Stephen J. Arnold (1997), "The Impact of Buyer Dependence on Buyer Opportunism in Buyer-Supplier Relationships: The Moderating Role of Relational Norms," Psychology and Marketing, 14 (8), 823-845. J oshi, Ashwin W. and Alexandra J. Campbell (2003), "Effect of Environmental Dynamism on Relational Governance in Manufacturer-Supplier Relationships: A Contingency Framework and an Empirical Test," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 31 (2), 176-188. 242 J oshi, Ashwin W. and Rodney L. Stump (1999), "The Contingent Effect of Specific Asset Investments on Joint Action in Manufacturer-Supplier Relationships: An Empirical Test of the Moderating Role of Reciprocal Asset Investments, Uncertainty, and Trust," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 27(3), 291-305. J oskow, Paul L. (1987), "Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets," The American Economic Review, 77 (1), 168-185. Kale, Prashant, Harbir Singh, and Howard Perlmutter (2000), "Learning and Protection of Proprietary Assets in Strategic Alliances: Building Relational Capital," Strategic Management Journal, 21 (3), 217-237. Kim, Daekwan, S. Tamer Cavusgil, and Roger J. Calantone (2006), "Information System Innovations and Supply Chain Management: Channel Relationships and Firm Performance," J oumal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 34(1), 40-54. Klaas, Brian S., John McClendon, and Thomas W. Gainey (1999), "HR Outsourcing and Its Impact: The Role of Transaction Costs," Personnel Psychology, 52 (1), 113-136. Klein, Saul (1989), "A Transaction Cost Explanation of Vertical Control in International Markets," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 17 (3), 253-260. Klein, Saul, Gary L. Frazier, and Victor J. Roth (1990), "A Transaction Cost Analysis Model of Channel Integration in International Markets," Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (2), 196-208. Klein, Saul and Victor J. Roth (1993), "Satisfaction with International Marketing Channels," J oumal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 21 (1), 39-44. Kogut, Bruce, Weijian Shan, and Gordon Walker (1992), "The Make-or- Cooperate Decision in the Context of an Industry Network, " in Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Action, Nitin Nohria and R.G. Eccles, Eds. Boston, MA.: Harvard Business School Press, 348-365. Kohli, Ajay K. and Bernard J. J aworski (1990), "Market Orientation: The Construct, Research Propositions, and Managerial Implications," J oumal of Marketing, 54(2), l-17. 243 Kraatz, Matthew S. (1998), "Learning by Association? Interorganizational Networks and Adaptation to Environmental Change," The Academy of Management Journal, 41 (6), 621-643. Krackhardt, David (1992), "The Strength of Strong Ties: The Importance of Philos in Organizations," in Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Actions, Nitin Nohria and Robert G. Eccles, Eds. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 216-239. Krafft, Manfred (1999), "An Empirical Investigation of the Antecedents of Sales Force Control Systems," Journal of Marketing, 63 (3), 120-134. Lawrence, Paul R. and Jay W. Lorsch (1967), Organization and Environment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration. Lee, Dong-J in (1998), "Developing International Strategic Alliances Between Exporters and Importers: The Case of Australian Exporters," International Journal of Research in Marketing, 15 (4), 335-348. Leiblein, Michael J. and Douglas J. Miller (2003), "An Empirical Examination of Transaction-and Finn-Level Influences on the Vertical Boundaries of the F inn," Strategic Management Journal, 24 (9), 839-859. Leiblein, Michael J ., Jeffrey J. Reuer, and Frederic Dalsace (2002), "Do Make or Buy Decision Matter? The Influence of Organizational Governance on Technological Performance," Strategic Management Journal, 23 (9), 817- 833. Levy, David T. (1985), "The Transactions Cost Approach to Vertical Integration: An Empirical Examination," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67 (3), 438-445. Lieberman, Marvin B. (1991), "Determinants of Vertical Integration: An Empirical Test," The Journal of Industrial Economics, 39 (5), 451-466. Lunsford, J. Lynn (2007), "Jet Blues: Boeing Scrambles to Repair Problems With New Plane," in The Wall Street Journal. New York. Macneil, Ian R. (1980), The New Social Contract. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Madhavan, Ravindranath, Balaji R. Koka, and John E. Prescott (1998), "Networks in Transition: How Industry Events (Re)shape Interfirm Relationships," Strategic Management Journal, 19 (5), 439-459. 244 Majumdar, Sumit K. and Venkatram Ramaswamy (1994), "Explaining Downstream Integration," Managerial and Decision Economics, 15 (2), 119-129. Masten, Scott E. (1984), "The Organization of Production: Evidence from the Aerospace Industry," Journal of Law and Economics, 27 (2), 403-417. Masten, Scott E., James W. Meehan Jr., and Edward A. Snyder (1991), "The Costs of Organization," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7 (1), 1-25. McEvily, Bill and Akbar Zaheer (1999), "Bridging Ties: A Source of Firm Heterogeneity in Competitive Capabilities," Strategic Management Journal, 20 (12), 1133-1156. McNaughton, Rod B. (2002), "The Use of Multiple Export Channels by Small Knowledge-Intensive Firms," International Marketing Review, 19 (2/3), 190-203. Miles, Raymond E. and Charles C. Snow (1986), "Organizations: New Concepts for New Forms," California Management Review, 34 (4), 62-73. Moller, Kristian and David T. Wilson (1995), Business Marketing: An Interaction and Network Perspective. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Monteverde, Kirk and David J. Teece (1982), "Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry," Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (1), 206-213. Nahapiet, Janine and Sumantra Ghoshal (1998), "Social Capital, Intellectual Capital and the Organizational Advantage, " The Academy of Management Review, 38 (2), 242-266. Noordewier, Thomas G., George John, and John R. Nevin (1990), "Performance Outcomes of Purchasing Arrangements in Industrial Buyer-Vendor Relationships," Journal of Marketing, 54(4), 80-93. Ouchi, William G. (1980), "Markets, Bureaucracies and Clans," Administrative Science Quarterly, 25 (1), 129-141. Oxley, Joanne E. (1999), "Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance: The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-Firm Alliances," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38 (3), 283-309. 245 Oxley, Joanne E. and Rachelle C. Sampson (2004), "The Scope and Governance of International R&D Alliances," Strategic Management Journal, 25 (8/9), 723-749. Parkhe, Arvind (1993), "Strategic Alliance Structuring: A Game Theoretic and Transaction Cost Examination of Interfirrn Cooperation," The Academy of Management Journal, 36 (4), 794-829. Parkhe, Arvind, Stanley Wasserman, and David A. Ralston (2006), "New Frontiers in Network Theory Development," The Academy of Management Review, 31 (3), 560-568. Pilling, Bruce K., Lawrence A. Crosby, and Donald W. Jackson, Jr. (1994), "Relational Bonds in Industrial Exchange: An Experimental Test of the Transaction Cost Economic Framework," Journal of Business Research, 30(3), 237-251. Podolny, Joel M. (1994), "Market Uncertainty and the Social Character of Economic Exchange," Administrative Science Quarterly, 39 (3), 458-483. ---- (1993), "A Status-Based Model of Market Competition," The American Journal of Sociology, 98 (4), 829-872. Polanyi, Michael (1966), The Tacit Dimension. New York: Anchor Day. Poppo, Laura and Todd Zenger (1998), "Testing Alternative Theories of the Firm: Transaction Cost, Knowledge-Based, and Measurement Explanations for Make-or-Buy Decisions in Information Services," Strategic Management Journal, 19 (9), 853-877. Powell, Walter W. (1990), "Neither Market nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization," in Research in Organizational Behavior, B. Shaw and L. L. Cummings, Eds. Vol. 12. Greenwich CT: JAI Press, 295-336. Powell, Walter W., Kenneth W. Koput, and Laurel Smith-Doerr (1996), "Interorganizational Collaboration and the Locus of Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology," Administrative Science Quarterly, 41 (1), 116-145. Powell, Walter W. and Laurel Smith-Doerr (1994), "Networks and Economic Life," in The Handbook of Economic Sociology, N.J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, Eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 368-402. Provan, Keith G. and Steven J. Skinner (1989), "Interorganizational Dependence and Control as Predictors Of Opportunism in Dealer-Supplier Relationships," The Academy of Management Journal, 32 (1), 202-212. 246 Raub, Werner and J eroen Weesie (1990), "Reputation and Efficiency in Social Interactions: An Example of Network Effects," The American J oumal of Sociology, 96(3), 626-654. Reuer, Jeffrey J. and Africa Arino (2002), "Contractual Renegotiations in Strategic Alliances," Journal of Management, 28 (1), 47-68. Rindfleisch, Aric and Jan B. Heide (1997), "Transaction Cost Analysis: Past, Present, and Future Applications," Journal of Marketing, 61 (4), 30-54. Rindfleisch, Aric and Christine Moorman (2001), "The Acquisition and Utilization of Information in New Product Alliances: A Strength-of-Ties Perspective," Journal of Marketing, 65 (2), 1-18. Robertson, Thomas S. and Hubert Gatignon (1998), "Technology Development Mode: A Transaction Cost Conceptualization," Strategic Management Journal, 19(6), 515-531. Rokkan, Aksel 1., Jan B. Heide, and Kenneth H. Wathne (2003), "Specific Investments in Marketing Relationships: Expropriation and Bonding Effects," Journal of Marketing Research, 40(2), 210-224. Rowley, Timothy J. (1997), "Moving Beyond Dyadic Ties: A Network Theory of Stakeholder Influences," The Academy of Management Review, 22 (4), 887-910. Rowley, Timothy J ., Dean Behrens, and David Krackhardt (2000), "Redundant Governance Structures: An Analysis of Structural and Relational Embeddedness in the Steel and Semiconductor Industries," Strategic Management Journal, 21 (3), 369-386. Sako, Mari and Susan Helper (1998), "Determinants of Trust in Supplier Relations: Evidence from the Automotive Industry in Japan and the United States," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 34 (3), 387-417. Schilling, Melissa A. and H. Kevin Steensma (2002), "Disentangling the Theories of Firm Boundaries: A Path Model and Empirical Test," Organization Science, 13 (4), 387-401. Shan, Weijan, Gordon Walker, and Bruce Kogut (1994), "Interfirm Cooperation and Startup Innovation in the Biotechnology Industry," Strategic Management Journal, 15 (5), 387-394. 247 Shelanski, Howard A. and Peter G. Klein (1995), "Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and Assessment," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11 (2), 335-361. Simon, Herbert A. (1961), Administrative Behavior (2nd ed.). New York: MacMillan. Simonin, Bernard L. (1999), "Ambiguity and the Process of Knowledge Transfer in Strategic Alliances," Strategic Management Journal, 20 (7), 595-623. Skarmeas, Dionisis, Constantine S. Katsikeas, and Bodo B. Schlegelmilch (2002), "Drivers of Commitment and Its Impact on Performance in Cross-Cultural Buyers-Seller Relationships: The Importer's Perspective," Journal of International Business Studies, 33 (4), 757-783. Steensma, H. Kevin, Louis Marino, K. Mark Weaver, and Pat H. Dickson (2000), "The Influence of National Culture on the Formation of Technology Alliances by Entrepreneurial F irms," The Academy of Management Journal, 43 (5), 951-973. Stinchombe, Arthur (1985), "Contracts as Hierarchical Documents," in Organization Theory and Project Management, A. L. Stinchombe and C. A. Heimer, Eds. Oslo: Norwegian University Press, 121-171. Stremersch, Stefan, Allen M. Weiss, Benedict G. C. Dellaert, and Ruud T. Frambach (2003), "Buying Modular Systems in Technology-Intensive Markets," Journal of Marketing Research, 40(3), 335-350. Stump, Rodney L. (1995), "Antecedents of Purchasing Concentration: A Transaction Cost Explanation," Journal of Business Research, 34 (2), 145- 157. Stump, Rodney L. and Jan B. Heide (1996), "Controlling Supplier Opportunism in Industrial Relationships," Journal of Marketing Research, 33 (4), 431- 441. Sutcliffe, Kathleen M. and Akbar Zaheer (1998), "Uncertainty in the Transaction Environment: An Empirical Test," Strategic Management Journal, 19 (1), 1-23. Uzzi, Brian (1997), "Social Structure and Competition in Interfirrn Networks: The Paradox of Embeddedness," Administrative Science Quarterly, 42 (1), 35- 67. 248 ---- (1996), "The Sources and Consequences of Embeddedness for the Economic Performance of Organizations: The Network Effect," American Sociological Review, 61 (4), 674-698. Valente, Thomas W. (1995), Network Models of the Diffusion of Innovations. Cresskill, NJ: Hampton Press. Van de Ven, Andrew H. (1986), "Central Problems in the Management of Innovation," Management Science, 32(5), 590-607. Walker, Gordon, Bruce Kogut, and Weijian Shan (1997), "Social Capital, Structural Holes and the Formation of an Industry Network," Organization Science, 8 (2), 109-125. Walker, Gordon and David Weber (1987), "Supplier Competition, Uncertainty, and Make-or-Buy Decisions," The Academy of Management Journal, 30 (3), 589-596. ---- (1984), "A Transaction Cost Approach to Make-or-Buy Decisions," Administrative Science Quarterly, 29 (3), 373-391. Wasserman, Stanley and Katherine Faust (1994), Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wathne, Kenneth H., Harald Biong, and Jan B. Heide (2001), "Choice of Supplier in Embedded Markets: Relationship and Marketing Program Effects," Journal of Marketing, 65 (2), 54-66. Wathne, Kenneth H. and Jan B. Heide (2000), "Opportunism in Interfirrn Relationships: Forms, Outcomes, and Solutions," Journal of Marketing, 64 (4), 36-51. ---- (2004), "Relationship Governance in a Supply Chain Network," Journal of Marketing, 68 (1), 73-89. Weiss, Allen M. and Erin Anderson (1992), "Converting from Independent to Employee Salesforces: The Role of Perceived Switching Costs," Journal of Marketing Research, 29 (1), 101-115. Weiss, Allen M. and Nancy Kurland (1997), "Holding Distribution Channel Relationships Together: The Role of Transaction-Specific Assets and Length of Prior Relationships," Organization Science, 8 (6), 612-623. Widener, Sally K. and Frank H. Selto (1999), "Management Control Systems and Boundaries of the F inn: Why Do Firms Outsource Internal Auditing Activities?" Journal of Management Accounting Research, 1 1, 45-73. 249 Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), "Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives," Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (2), 269-296. ---- (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press. ---- (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free Press. ---- (1993), "Opportunism and Its Critics," Managerial and Decision Economics, 14(2), 97-107. Wuyts, Stefan, Stefan Stremersch, Christopher Van Den Bulte, and Philip Hans Franses (2004), "Vertical Marketing Systems for Complex Products: A Triadic Perspective," Journal of Marketing Research, 41 (4), 479-487. Yamagishi, Toshio, Mary R. Gillmore, and Karen S. Cook (1988), "Network Connections and the Distribution of Power in Exchange Networks," The American Journal of Sociology, 93 (4), 833-851. Zaheer, Akbar and Geoffrey G. Bell (2005), "Benefiting from Network Position: F irrn Capabilities, Structural Holes, and Performance," Strategic Management Journal, 26 (9), 809-825. Zaheer, Akbar and N. Venkatraman (1995), "Relational Governance as an Interorganizational Strategy: An Empirical Test of the Role of Trust in Economic Exchange," Strategic Management Journal, 16 (5), 373-392. 250