A in 3.1 L _ I 2%. . s. . a.“ .. R1: .b‘ 5.. .u r... (“gnaw . 4?. , t... '1‘:- ~ .1. QI..WJ...J as Lu}... 1. 3...“. v . .9} .2! “(V109 ‘ :0 bw... , I :1 : “I“..xmrawohm _ 1mm») 1 2mm» . $93.. {.1. a. 1);! 31.13- PLDI , {I L .2... .. :1...“ 1 . .(fcr H‘nrfluoi, g“ .LIBRARY 2 C, 03 Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled GREENS, SUITS, AND BUREAUCRATS: A SOCIOLOGICAL STUDY OF DYNAMIC ORGANIZATIONAL RELATIONSHIPS IN ENERGY EFFICIENT APPLIANCE POLICY presented by RACHAEL LEAH SHWOM-EVELICH has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the PhD. degree in SociologL / V ’Major Professor’s Signaturé / 0 I73 L Q0 0 Q Date MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Employer PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5108 KIProj/Achres/ClRC/Dateoueindd GREENS, SUITS, AND BUREAUCRATS: A SOCIOLOGICAL STUDY OF DYNAMIC ORGANIZATIONAL RELATIONSHIPS IN ENERGY EFFICIENT APPLIANCE POLICY By Rachael Leah Shwom-Evelich A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Sociology 2008 ABSTRACT GREENS, SUITS, AND BUREAUCRATS: A SOCIOLOGICAL STUDY OF DYNAMIC ORGANIZATIONAL RELATIONSHIPS IN ENERGY EFFICIENT APPLIANCE POLICY By Rachael Leah Shwom-Evelich In this dissertation I develop an approach to understanding dynamic organizational relations and the processes of environmental degradation and reform. To do this, I draw on environmental and organizational sociology to inform an empirical study of interorganizational relationships in defining and promoting energy efficient appliances in the United States (US). The dissertation follows a three paper approach which involves a) an overall introduction to the substantive issue of appliance energy efficiency in the US; b) producing three separate and stand alone articles of publishable quality to be submitted to professional journals; and c) an overall conclusion. The three articles are as follows: 1) a synthetic literature review identifying five lessons that organizational sociology and environmental sociology can learn from each other to advance our sociological understanding of organizations, energy issues, and climate change 2) a qualitative case study of the changing relationships between business, government and environmental and energy advocacy organizations around mandatory appliance efficiency standards supporting the development of a context-dependent theory of ecological modernization and treadmill of production theories in environmental sociology and 3) a network analysis of public government, business and energy efficiency advocate’s interorganizational relationships and its influence on subsequent organizational behaviors in the appliance energy efficiency field. The second and third articles are based on extensive archival research on organizational negotiations Of public record over defining energy efficient appliances in both regulatory and voluntary settings. Finally I will provide an overall conclusion that brings together the most significant findings of each individual article in anticipation of a synthetic approach to the study of organizations in environmental reform. Copyright by RACHAEL LEAH SHWOM-EVELICH 2008 This dissertation is dedicated to my husband, Nicholas Evelich, and daughter, Marishka Rose Evelich, who gave me up to this project and provided the support, love, and occasional joyful distraction that enabled me to persevere. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS If any singular personal experience can demonstrate the importance of social networks and the resources that flow through them to success, it is perhaps my five years spent in graduate school. First, I have benefitted immensely from my Committee’s guidance. My chair, Tom Dietz, has imparted a wonderfully broad education in the environmental social sciences by supporting my participation in numerous interdisciplinary environmental experiences and engaging with me as I searched for my own sociological views on environmental issues. Pragmatically, he gave thoughtfiil comments on drafts and sure-handed guidance in balancing the demands of academic life. Linda Kalof provided me sound training in social science research methods and helpful comments and encouragement. I am indebted to Ken Frank who introduced me to social network analysis and reassuringly kept me calm and grounded in the ftmdamentals as I encountered the methodological complexities of network analysis. Aaron McCright has been generous with his time as he has not only provided thoughtful comments and careful editing, but also immensely helpful discussions of theories on social movements, environment, organizations, and power. There have been many others that have made this work possible and enjoyable. I owe a particular thanks to Glee Murray at the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy and Brenda Edwards at the US. Department Of Energy for their help in gathering archival materials for this project. George Moyer’s help with data entry and Leslie Pearlman’s technical expertise in network analysis software were also greatly appreciated. A generous fellowship from Michigan State University’s Environmental Science Policy Program provided the time to develop my dissertation proposal into a full vi grant. As a result, this dissertation has enjoyed support from the National Science Foundation’s Innovation, Organization, and Change Program (Grant # 0724905). A Dissertation Completion Fellowship from the Michigan State University College of Social Sciences was also helpful in providing uninterrupted writing time in the fall of 2008. Equally important as the help that flowed through these professional networks was the support I have received from my fi'iends and family. My mother and father raised me to value education and have never wavered in their encouragement of my pursuit even as it took us away from the east coast. No matter how busy or how far away, the Renegade Sociologists (Julie, Elisha, Lori, Amy, Karijn, Jessica and Cathy) were there to advise on how to best format a dissertation, commiserate on another rejected paper, go for a run, and pour a good glass of wine. I owe a debt of gratitude to those friends, Lia Farrow (via Hong Kong) and Elisha Marr, and family, particularly my in-laws Irene and Vince, who helped take care of my daughter whenever they could. TO my husband and my daughter, who have allowed me to retreat into the isolation of writing and taken up all non-dissertation responsibilities, you are both the inspiration for this work and the reason I am glad to be done. vii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................... x LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................. xi KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS ..................................................................... xii INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1 Interorganizational Relations in Energy Efficiency Policy ............................................. 1 Theoretical Framework: Organizational and Environmental Sociology ........................ 4 Why the Case of Appliance Energy Efficiency? A Historical Perspective on Energy Efficiency and US. Policy on Energy and Environment ................................................ 9 Energy Policy History up to 1973: Cheap and Available ......................................... 10 The 1970’s: A Time of Change ................................................................................ 12 Organizations and the Evolution of Energy Efficiency Policy Post 1973 ................. 16 Methods: Qualitative and Quantitative Network Approaches ...................................... 25 Dissertation Research Objectives .................................................................................. 29 CHAPTER ONE .................................................................................... 32 Strengthening Sociological Perspectives on Organizations and the Environment: Five Lessons from Organizational and Environmental Sociology 32 Introduction ................................................................................................................... 32 No organization is an island — socially or ecologically ................................................. 35 Organizational environmental outcomes and their measurement matter ...................... 39 Corporate environmental actions vary and are context-dependent ............................... 42 Cooperation and cooptation are two sides Of the same coin ......................................... 51 The cumulative environmental impacts of organizational change are constrained by system tendencies .......................................................................................................... 57 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 61 CHAPTER TWO .................................................................................... 63 A Context-Dependent Theory of Green Consumer Goods: Conditions of Dynamic Power Relations in the Struggle for Energy Efficient Appliances .................................... 63 Introduction ................................................................................................................... 63 Current Limits to Understanding Environmental Degradation and Improvement ........ 65 A Context Dependent Theorization of Ecological Modernization and Treadmill of Production ...................................................................................................................... 70 Methods ......................................................................................................................... 75 The Shifting Political Economy of US. Appliance Efficiency ..................................... 76 The Face of Treadmill of Production 1981-1986: Reaganism, Pre-Regulation, and Resistance ...................................................................................................................... 81 The Face of Ecological Modernization 1992-2001: Pre-negotiated Standards and Market Transformation .................................................................................................. 88 Discussion and Conclusion ............................................................................................ 94 viii CHAPTER THREE ............................................................................... 101 Friend or Foe? Energy Efficiency Advocacy Organizations’ Embeddedness and Decisions to Partner with Business .............................................................. 101 Introduction ................................................................................................................. 101 Theoretical Approach .................................................................................................. 104 Methods and Analysis ................................................................................................. 110 Network Construction .............................................................................................. 110 Independent Variable: Cohesive Subgroup Membership ....................................... 113 Independent Variable: EEAO decision to co-author a paper for summer study with business in 1998-2000 ............................................................................................. 114 Independent Variable: EEAO demographics .......................................................... 114 Dependent Variables: EEAO decision to cO-author a paper for summer study with business in 2006-2008 ............................................................................................. 1 15 EEAOs and the Energy Efficiency Field Pre-2001 ..................................................... 116 The Energy Efficiency Field 2001-2006 ..................................................................... 123 Discussion and Conclusions ........................................................................................ 129 CONCLUSION .................................................................................... 13 l Advancing Sociological Perspectives and Research on Organizations and the Environment ................................................................................................................ 1 3 1 APPENDIX A .................................................................................................................. 136 Full list of face-to-face meetings on the definition and promotion of energy efficient residential appliances available on public record from 1980 to 2006. ........................ 136 APPENDIX B .................................................................................................................. 138 Organizational and Event Subgroup Memberships ..................................................... 138 LITERATURE CITED ........................................................................... 182 ix LIST OF TABLES Table 3.1: 1993-2000 Cohesive Subgroup Memberships .............................................. 122 Table 3.2: 2001-2006 Cohesive Subgroup Memberships .............................................. 126 Table 3.3: 2001-2006 Cohesive Subgroup Organizational Demographics .................... 128 Table 3.4: Logistic Regression Results for Market Transformation Subgroup Membership and Business Co-authorship ....................................................................... 129 Table 1.1: Face-tO-face meetings of available public record on appliance energy efficiency 1980-2006. ...................................................................................................... 137 Table 3.5: Cohesive Subgroup Organizational and Event Membership for 1994-2000. 139 Table 3.6: Cohesive Subgroup Organizational and Event Membership for 2001-2006. 160 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 3.1: Cohesive Subgroups of Events and Organizational Sectors for 1994-2000.121 Figure 3.2: Cohesive Subgroups of Events and Organizational Sectors for 2001-2006.127 xi ACEEE AN OPR CEC DOE EEAO EIS EMT ESMO EPCA GDP NAECA NECPA NOPR NRDC SERP TNESMOs TOP KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers Advanced Notice of Public Rulemaking California Energy Commission Department of Energy (US) Energy Efficiency Advocacy Organization Environmental Impact Statement Ecological modernization theory Environmental social movement organization Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975 Gross Domestic Product National Appliance Energy Conservation Act of 1987 and 1992 National Energy Conservation and Policy Act of 1978 Notice of Public Rulemaking Natural Resources Defense Council Super Efficient Refi'igerator Program Transnational Environmental Social Movement Organizations Treadmill Of production xii INTRODUCTION Interorganizational Relations in Energy Efficiency Policy Climate change has been cited by scientists and politicians alike as one of the most pressing problems facing society today (Alley, Bemtsen, Bindoff, Chen, Chidthaisong, and Friedlingstein 2007; Gore 2006; Stern 2006). New cooperative approaches between business, government, and the non-profit sector are often identified as one of the keys to meeting the complex challenges in mitigation and adaptation that climate change currently presents (Brewer and Stern 2005). But the question of how and when organizations from these sectors, which have Often historically been at odds with each other, may come to work together has been relatively unexamined. What factors influence whether non-profit, business, and governmental organizations recognize mutual interests and see fit to work together? More specifically, what political, social, and economic conditions influence the willingness to work together? And how do past organizational interactions and influence subsequent participation in partnerships and new cooperative approaches? One arena of climate change mitigation where diverse interorganizational relationships have developed is energy efficiency policy. Currently greenhouse gas producing fossil fuels — coal, oil and natural gas — provide more than 85% of all energy consumed in the United States (Energy Information Administration 2008). Reducing the United States’ use of these fuels is one of the major pathways to mitigating its contributions to climate change. The reduction Of energy demand through improvement in energy efficiency is Often perceived as one of the most politically and economically feasible ways to mitigate the U.S.’s contribution to climate change (Hays 2000; Pacala and Socolow 2004). Yet, a review of energy efficiency history in the US. reveals that the path to improving efficiency has not been particularly straightforward or smooth. My dissertation seeks to begin to understand the complex and changing relationships between non-profit, governmental, and private business organizations around the issue of decreasing US. energy use from a sociological perspective by focusing on organizational relationships and the factors that influence their evolving structure and actions. Following the initial oil embargo of 1973, a complex network of nonprofit energy efficiency organizations, manufacturers of products, energy utilities, and state and federal government agencies has formed around negotiations over the definition of energy efficient products and services and how to promote them. This organizational network has evolved over the last 30 years to establish multiple institutional arrangements for defining energy efficient products including federal and state mandatory minimum energy efficiency standards along with voluntary efficiency specifications. All of these institutional arrangements have been characterized at different points by both combative and cooperative relationships between the three sectors, though state and federal mandatory standard efforts have been particularly wrought with conflict and lawsuits. In addition to defining energy efficiency, many have sought to promote energy efficiency products through a variety of interorganizational arrangements including: funding research and development, conducting demonstrations and field tests, providing commercialization incentives, marketing and consumer education, grants loans and tax incentives, voluntary programs, and bulk purchases. Lighting, appliances and buildings have been at the center of these efforts. This study will focus on residential appliances since the definition and promotion of efficient lighting and buildings entails a different set of actors and institutional arrangements and deserves to be studied in their own right. My dissertation chronicles organizational participation in public forums that sought to define and promote energy efficient residential appliances. I use this data to identify which organizations are highly active in different venues, what organizations they are interacting with in these actions, how this changes over time, and what are some outcomes from this participation. I argue that although important interactions between organizations often take place “off-the-record” these interactions are likely based on existing network structure and often manifest publicly at some point. The resulting network data is analyzed to help answer the following three questions in a series of three articles: 1. What does a dialogue between environmental and organizational sociology have to offer in improving our understanding of fundamental questions in both fields? How can the advancement of these theories provide insights into the root causes of and solutions for climate change? 2. What were the relationships of the non-profit organizations with government and business organizations around energy efficiency from 1973 to 2006? What changes have occurred and what external factors are associated with these changes? Do these findings support the predictions of political economic theories of the environment in environmental sociology? 3. How does participation in events influence the subsequent network structure via participation in subsequent events and partnerships? Does participation in events with other organizations and influence the stance an organization takes on an issue? Do these findings support or nullify claims of Open systems theories of organizational sociology? Theoretical Framework: Organizational and Environmental Sociology In this dissertation, I locate the production and mitigation of environmental problems in industrial and post-industrial nations as outcomes of organizational and inter- organizational processes (Perrow 1997). The formal organization is the overwhelmingly dominant organizing form for business, government and social movement organizations (Presthus and Presthus 1962; Zald 2000). The capitalist political economic environment these organizations conduct their environmental decision-making within is extensively theorized in environmental sociology (M01 and Spaargaren 2000; Roberts and Grimes 2002; Schnaiberg 1980). However, despite a growing literature focusing on organizations and the natural environment (Bansal and Gao 2006), little has been done to connect these understandings of organizational behavior in political economic theories of the environment to those in organizational sociology. I argue that a truly sociological study of organizations and the natural environment can yield great insights into the roots of and solutions to environmental problems. To enable a sociological study of this area, I seek to build an integrative understanding of organizations and networks in environmental sociology. Environmental Sociology undertakes the problematic of why modern societies tend towards environmental destruction (Buttel and Gijswijt 2000). It often presents broad structural theories of how and why people, societal institutions, and organizations cause environmental disruption (i.e. treadmill of production, world systems theories). At the same time, work on the environmental movement and New Ecological Paradigm has produced a robust literature on the social psychology of individual’s environmental behaviors. While these theories of environmental sociology have provided many insights on environmental destruction and reform, they have drawn on limited organizational level understandings of how these processes of environmental degradation take place and the organizational/sectoral variations in these behaviors and outcomes. The political economic theories within environmental sociology focus explicitly on the interactions between the organization of political and economic systems and technology in environmental impacts and their mitigation. Allan Schnaiberg’s (Schnaiberg 1980) breakthrough political economic analysis of environmental problems and subsequent work on the treadmill of production is one such line of work. Schnaiberg theorizes that the institutional arrangements under monopoly capitalism result in the competition and concentration of capital that leads to increases in capital investment and technological efficiency. These conditions result in the increasing speeds of withdrawals Of material resources from and additions of these material resources transformed in the form of waste to the environment. This cycle is referred to as the treadmill of production (TOP). In addition to theorizing industrial development and its environmental impacts, Schnaiberg and colleagues (Gould, Pellow, and Schnaiberg 2004; Schnaiberg 1994) have also theorized and empirically studied the political economy of the state and social movement efforts for slowing the treadmill. Contradicting much of what is said by treadmill of production advocates, M01 and Spaargaren (M01 1995; Mo] and Spaargaren 2000) argue that a reflexive ecological consciousness will result in a new politics and transformation of industrial practices and technological innovation that will benefit the environment. This stream of theory has focused more on the development of public-private partnerships and corporate voluntary environmental actions. Much of the research that has followed has focused on the institutional and cultural conditions under which ecological modernization proceeds, such as strength of the environmental state and extent of public understanding of science (Cohen 1998; Sonnenfeld and Mo] 2002). The assumptions and predicted outcomes of ecological modernization theory have come under close scrutiny by many environmental sociologists (Fisher and F reudenburg 2001; York and Rosa 2003). I argue that underlying the debate between these two theoretical approaches are differences in the understanding of power relations between the state, society, and industry. Focusing on the organizational level of these relationships allows us to interrogate these two theories more comprehensively. Support for this approach in environmental sociology emerges from political sociology where multiple scholars have utilized organizational theory and analysis successfully. State-centered theorists have argued that theory of the state should move away from theorizing the state as monolithic and recognize differentiation. These theorists, such as Skocpol and Amenta, see the state as Weber did, “as a set of organizations, but with unique functions and missions.” (Amenta 2005). Hooks (1993) utilizes organizational theory to analyze competing theories of the state and the conditions under which they were accurate. Additionally, I take a cue from Knoke (1990) and his political structuralist approach in viewing each sector as populations of organizations and people carrying out these power relations daily through activities that can be documented and analyzed as a network. The field Of organizational sociology is made up of several theories that attempt to explain and predict how organizations and the people in them will behave in varying organizational structures, cultures, and circumstances. Most recently, the Open system perspective (Scott, Davis, and Richard 2007) views organizational actions as being embedded in broader environments. Open systems theories include Harman and Freeman’s (1977) organizational ecology model, Pfeffer and Salancik’s (1978) resource dependence model, and Meyer and Rowan’s (197 7) institutional theory. Open system theories are gaining recognition across fields in sociology for understanding the constitution of organizational life. Bansal and Gao (2006:463) conclude that “the new institutional analysis has been the dominant theoretical theme among studies with a natural environment context, likely because institutional forces have such a significant role in environmental issues.” New institutional theory (DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Powell and DiMaggio 1991) has critiqued the classical and neoclassical models of organizations highlighting that all organizational behavior is a product of an embedded collective rationality. This means that organizations act by following scripts or templates for behavior provided by those around them. This can lead to organizational isomorphism, the phenomenon of organizations becoming increasingly homogenous in structure, beliefs, and actions. Early new institutionalism focused on how symbolic systems, cultural scripts, and mental models reproduce themselves and become accepted and familiar parts of our lives. DiMaggio and Powell (1983) proposed that this occurs through three types of processes: coercive, normative, and mimetic. Critiques of the emphasis of homogeneity in organizations asked how change and heterogeneity in organizational forms occurred. If the theory predicted organizations will look and behave similarly what accounts for variation and sources of change? To account for change in new institutional theory, many organizational scholars have sought to integrate “Old” institutional theory that focuses on the political aspects of interorganizational interactions, such as conflicts of interests and cooptation (Selznick 1966). The marriage of the two theories has resulted in an understanding of organizations as being embedded in their organizational environment which forms a collective understanding of the range of actions they may take (Greenwood and Hinings 1996). Organizations may act strategically from this situated understanding of rational action. Campbell (2005) has proposed multiple mechanisms of organizational change such as diffusion, translation, bricolage, and network cultivation. The concept of organizational fields, groups of organizations engaged with the same activity or issue, has evolved to understand organizations as engaged with multiple and often conflicting institutions. Hoffman (1999)added that fields should be seen as contested centers of debate with power dynamics, where competing interests negotiate the interpretation of what they each consider as key issues. Research has focused on the extent to which organizational fields were fragmented, contained multiple institutional influences, and were thus subject to change and transformation. Open systems organizational theories provide three important tools for thinking about interorganizational relationships between non-profits, governments and business organizations in defining and promoting energy efficiency. First, open systems theories seek to explain how interorganizational relationships influence organizational behavior and decision-making, proposing a number of mechanisms by which organizational influence occurs. The understanding of an organizational field being able to be organized around an issue, such as defining and promoting energy efficient appliances, is particularly useful in being able to examine cross-sectoral organizational relationships. Second, open system thinking generated the idea that the criteria by which organizations make decisions are Often generated by other groups and institutions outside and include criteria such as organizational legitimacy. This recognition of external conditions is in synch with theories of political economy in environmental sociology. Finally, open systems theory, particularly new institutionalism, has struggled with organizational homogeneity, heterogeneity, and transformation and has evolved to develop some nuanced understandings of the “rational” and “irrational” aspects Of organizational decision-making and mechanisms of change that are useful in examining the evolution of energy and environmental issues. Why the Case of Appliance Energy Efficiency? A Historical Perspective on Energy Efl'rciency and U.S. Policy on Energy and Environment “Many energy techniques have reached unmistakable size and performance plateaus. This leveling-off is not a matter of technical limits but rather of prohibitive costs and unacceptable environmental impacts. Greater efficiency, reliability, and environmental compatibility have become new engineering goals.” (Smil 1994) A review of the history of energy efficiency of residential appliances in the broader context of U.S. energy and environmental policy highlights the unique aspects of this interorganizational field and its usefulness for the study of organizations and climate change. The production and consumption of energy is pervasive in its impacts on the environment and economy. American interests in increasing energy efficiency can’t and shouldn’t be examined without considering the larger context of energy resource management in the U.S. and its relations to energy and environmental policies. The interest in energy efficiency policy at any given time has been greatly determined by the extent of perceptions of negative environmental and economic impacts of energy use. Indeed the story leading to our current residential energy efficiency policies is, as the quote above indicates, a story of the mounting costs and negative environmental impacts of increasing energy supply. The ways in which broader energy policies and environmental policies impact the supply and availability of energy influences pricing and has a large impact on the dynamics of end user efficiency. Exploring all the ways that these policies are interrelated and impact our energy use is not within the scope of this project, but I will focus on the aspects that have most directly influenced the development of energy efficiency policy and the development Of interorganizational relationships chronicled in this dissertation. In this section I will first briefly describe the aspects of U.S. energy policy pre-1973 that have had direct impacts on the evolution of residential energy efficiency policy: the supply of cheap fossil fuel energy and the growth of electricity production and transmission infrastructure. I will then provide a brief organizational understanding of the energy and environmental policy changes that occurred starting in the early 1970’s that changed the way the U.S. has managed energy and began to shift attention towards energy efficiency. Energy Policy History up to 1973: Cheap and Available The U.S. has developed as a “fossil-fueled civilization”, moving away from wood and waterpower and towards coal and oil, since the turn of the 20th century. Until 1973 the U.S. achieved this dominance by managing energy policy almost exclusively on the 10 economic objective of keeping energy cheap to fuel economic growth (Andrews 2006). This Objective was reached through keeping supply growing ahead of demand. Increases in the cheap energy supply were realized through high American productivities in coal extraction, from 4 tons of coal per person per shifi in 1900 to 10 tons per person per shift in 1980 (Smil, 1994:171-172). The U.S. also found oil first in Pennsylvania and subsequently seemingly endless supplies in the southwest and west that worked in conjunction with declining world oil prices through 1970 to make oil a key part of the U.S. fuel mix (Smil, 1994:203). This cheap energy fireled the American per capita gross domestic product (GDP) to grow by an unprecedented 60% between 1950 and 1973 (Smil, 1994:204). In 1956 the first commercial nuclear reactor delivered power, adding a non-fossil fuel energy to the mix accounting for 19.3% of U.S. energy supply by 2005. Besides cheap fossil fuel energy that could be used in producing power for homes, the second major factor influencing residential energy use was the expansion of the national energy infrastructure system. Hughes (Hughes 1983) has documented the expansion of utilities from urban to national systems led to great emphasis on economics of scale, construction of larger stations in or near cities, the development Of high voltage links to transmit electricity from remote hydro-stations, the promotion of mass consumption, and the interconnection of smaller system in order to improve supply. In 1907, only 8 percent of all dwellings were using electricity; by 1932, this figure had risen to 67 percent. By 1932 considerably more than 80 percent of urban dwellings were electrified, while only 11 percent Of farm dwellings had electrical service. The economics of scale realized during this expansion period through the 1960s had two implications for energy production and management. First it meant that energy 11 production lent itself to becoming monopolistic and therefore municipal utilities disappeared while large private utilities came to control 94% of energy production and transmission. This monopolistic tendency facilitated the involvement of state and federal governments that regulated private utilities while also expanding their roles in producing energy. Second it meant that there was a large potential for increasing efficiency of the primary production of electricity. This allowed electricity to remain cheap even while demand increased (Energy Information Administration 1985; Energy Information Administration 1992). These trends influenced energy use in residences by keeping electricity cheap and increasingly available. The low prices provided a lack of incentive for the conservation of energy. Though electric lighting was invented in 1882, air conditioning in 1902, and many electric appliances (irons, vacuums, and cookers) were available in 1900, it was only during the post-world war II era and with the growing of the middle class that Americans could afford these technologies (Smil, 1994). Between 1945 and 1950 residential electricity consumption grew most rapidly, almost 14 percent a year. This expansion of both electricity production and consumption continued unfettered through most of the 1960’s (Energy Information Administration, 1985). The 1970’s: A Time of Change In the late 1960’s and early 1970’s major developments affect the price of fossil fuels on the world market and the expansion of electricity production and transmission discussed above. First, the cheap worldwide oil market began to constrict with the formation and subsequent actions of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries 12 (OPEC). Second, the growing environmental movement began to raise concerns about environmental degradation. And third, in reaction to these developments, federal and state governments passed a number Of environmental policies and increasing regulation of energy producers. As institutional theorists note, change is Often prompted by external shocks (F ligstein 1991; Jepperson 1991) and the 1973 Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) oil embargo and ensuing energy crisis was that shock for energy-users in the United States. Formed in 1960 to counter the large Oil corporations in the west, OPEC took the step of imposing an Oil embargo against the U.S. in response the United State’s support of Israel. At the time the U.S. was dependent on OPEC for 35% of its oil supply. The embargo led to a fivefold increase in the price of Oil. The threat to cheap energy prompted the federal government to begin to exert more intervention in energy markets. We saw some Of the first interest in exercising control over demand for electricity from President Richard Nixon. He urged the U.S. to turn down their thermostats, offered a proposal for daylight savings time, and for prohibiting the selling of gasoline on Sunday. However, the major focus of the reactions to the energy crisis continued to be on the supply side. The U.S. congress reacted by authorizing the development of a Trans-Alaskan pipeline to increase U.S. energy production. Nixon created the Federal Energy Office and appointed an "energy czar" with the power to allocate oil supplies. Nixon also requested the preparation of a plan, known as "Project Independence," to make the United States independent of imported Oil by 1985. Under this program, higher cost imported oil was effectively subsidized by price-controlled domestic oil, leading to an average price below the world-market level. 13 The policy produced the opposite effect of the original intent: subsidized imports, lower domestic production, and increases in foreign production (Miller 1995). In addition to the embargo’s impacts, the environmental movement’s successes started to increase the costs of increasing electricity production. In response to widespread protests to federal highway projects, the first piece of a wave of federal environmental legislation is passed — the National Environmental Protection Act of 1969. This act requires any project that receives federal funding with the potential to impact the environment to undergo a process where its environmental impacts were publicly reviewed before the project proceeded. The definition of actions requiring the environmental impact statement (EIS) included "major federal actions significantly affecting the human environment." Thus, before implementing any "major" project the agency must consider the environmental impacts Of that action, identify unavoidable environmental impacts and make this information available to the public in the EIS (Andrews, 1999). This was the first federal level policy that led to challenges to the siting and building of new power plants. State and local regulations added to these challenges. However, the real impact on power production plant siting would come in the late 1970’s and early 1980’s with the powerful anti-nuclear movement that effectively shut down the commissioning of nuclear electricity generating plants in the U.S. (Eckstein 1997). In addition, the federal government also passed the first regulations around air pollution heavily regulating emissions from existing plants. The recognition of U.S. vulnerability to foreign oil producers and increasing prices of supply side energy fuels, along with the slowing of increases of efficiencies from economies of scale and increasing difficulty and costs of siting new plants for 14 electricity producers, led to a national interest in empowering U.S. citizens to reduce their demand in energy for the first time in U.S. history. Energy efficiency began to even be seen by some as the easy solution. Hays (1991 :159) writes that energy-efficient innovations came “rather easily” as they “simultaneously reduced costs and advanced environmental objectives.” In discussing Options for mitigating climate change, Pacala and Socolow (2004) make the case that we currently have the technologies to stabilize increasing emissions over the next 50 years. They identify efficiency and conservation as having the most potential to do this. Indeed, the U.S. has become more energy efficient enabling a “decoupling” of economic growth and energy use where GDP has been able to grow at a faster rate than energy use (Energy Information Administration, 1992). In addition, Mazur and Rosa (1974) reported a decoupling of energy use from quality of life indices. However, overall energy consumption is still increasing. Though history may ascribe this decoupling to the clear recognition of the financial and environmental costs and benefits of energy efficiency, market supply and demand for energy efficiency did not materialize evenly across the economy. Academic and advocates interested in energy efficiency sought to understand the reasons for these market failures. They identified multiple barriers to market development for energy efficient lighting and appliances including distortion of energy prices by other U.S. energy policies, lack of consumer knowledge and understanding of long-term energy costs Of purchases or behaviors, and split incentives where one party purchases a product and another pays the operating costs (California Energy Commission, 2005). These “market ban'iers”, as they are referred to in the energy efficiency field, create the need for specific policies or actions to be undertaken in order 15 to increase energy efficient product availability and demand. To many, the most obvious and expedient policy to remedy this situation was the enactment of federally mandated minimum efficiency standards that would require appliances sold or buildings built to meet certain design or energy use requirements. However, a range of actions would eventually be taken and it is the question of how organizational sectors in society have re- organized tO address these market barriers through the definition and promotion of energy efficiency that is central to my dissertation. Organizations and the Evolution of Energy Efiiciency Policy Post 1973 The most visible and well documented struggles to institutionalize energy efficiency have been in efforts to influence the adoption of mandatory energy efficiency standards at the federal level. Mandatory energy efficiency standards establish regulations that force manufacturers to produce only products that meet certain energy use requirements. This is opposed to voluntary approaches that identify higher efficiency products and promote them, but do not require governmental action and do not legally enact requirements for manufacturers to only produce those products. There have been multiple factors that have affected efficiency advocates’ capacities to influence the adoption Of mandatory standards at federal and state levels. In reviewing the history of energy efficiency standards, I propose that there are two major sociopolitical conditions that have influenced the tactics of those nonprofit organizations advocating for mandated energy efficiency standards: 1) the federal administration in power and their openness to standards; 2) state government’s Openness to adopting minimum standards. 16 Presidential administrations have had a significant amount of influence on the success or failure of minimum energy efficiency standards. Following the 1973 Oil embargo, President Ford was the first to consider mandatory energy efficiency standards, and chose to make energy efficiency targets voluntary instead. The 20% voluntary reduction target in new appliance energy use was formalized through an executive order and then the adoption of the Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975. The Carter Administration, however, proposed that mandated energy efficiency standards should be adopted the National Energy Conservation and Policy Act of 1978 contained a provision for the Department of Energy (DOE) to develop new standards. The Department of Energy began this process, but before these requirements were finalized and implemented, the Reagan Administration took office. The Reagan administration was philosophically Opposed to market interventions and proposed “no standards” standards refusing to set them until 1985 when the federal courts overturned the administration’s policy. Standards were finally adopted in 1987 after manufacturers and energy efficiency advocates negotiated minimum standards on a number of products and President Reagan signed the National Appliances Energy Conservation Act (NAECA) into effect. In 1988 subsequent standards were passed on fluorescent lamp ballasts and in 1992 a number of standards for products such as lamps, electric motors, and commercial heating, cooling, and plumbing products were passed in the Energy Policy Act (Nadel 2002). The Department of Energy is authorized under NAECA to review and revise minimum energy efficiency levels. Under the Clinton Administration it did so for residential air- conditioning. George W. Bush’s administration then rolled back the Clinton administration standards arguing that the DOE did not adequately weigh the costs of 17 these new standards in its analysis. A court battle ensued where the case was eventually dropped with industry stating that it would rather put its time into preparing for the upcoming standards than continue dealing with the uncertainty a court battle brought (New York Times, March 18, 2004). More recently, energy efficiency advocates negotiated additional national standards for products not previously covered, such as commercial refrigeration. While the federal level struggled with the paralysis of shifting administrations, states that faced more immediate energy problems acted. Many states, such as California and New York, faced constraints in building new power generation capacity as a result of the increasing costs and environmentalist opposition, but also faced growing demand was attributable to growing economies, increasing populations and changes in household energy consumption. State actions to deal with energy supply and demand issues have provided important openings in the political opportunity structures that were often closed at the federal level. First, state energy efficiency standards were essential in driving manufacturer’s willingness to negotiate at the federal level. The California Energy Commission had been proposed to be established in California in 1972, but had been rejected by then Governor Ronald Reagan until the 1973 energy crisis (Rosenfeld 1999). In 1974, California adopted the Warren-Alquist Act that established the California Energy Commission with the authority to set appliance efficiency standards. The first standards in California went into place in 1976 and New York State followed. By 1986 six states had adopted mandate minimum efficiency standards on what could be sold in the state on one or more products. This patchwork presented a problem for national manufacturers that were seeking to maximize economies of scale, but were instead faced 18 with producing a number of products and shipping them to different states. This condition along with the federal courts decision on the Reagan administration’s “non-standards” standards provided the impetus for manufacturers to negotiate (N adel, 2002). In addition to adopting minimum energy efficiency standards, many public utilities commissions in states began to regulate utilities to collect “systems benefits charges.” These charges could be used to run “demand-side-management” programs that could encourage curbing of energy use to decrease peak energy demand problems without building new and expensive power plants. NECPA of 1978 required utilities to Offer on-site energy audits to residential customers. This law was an acknowledgment that saving energy could be cheaper than producing it. The additional regulatory roots of DSM programs go back to state government involvement in the regulation of energy utilities emerging in the early 1900’s and their role in rate setting. Energy efficiency advocates introduced the idea of “least cost planning” where additional power plant proposals underwent review and the cost of the additional supply was compared to the costs to reducing demand to prevent the need for the supply. These programs began to be implemented on a state to state basis in the early eighties and grew into the early 90’s (Etc 1996). To understand the process by which these sociopolitical changes have impacted this cross-sectoral organizational field Of energy efficiency I must look to organizational perceptions and reactions to these changes. Despite the fact that opportunities to implement minimum energy efficiency standards are often unviable politically, a wide variety of organizations from government, the nonprofit and private sectors have coalesced around the specific issue of promoting innovation and diffusion of energy 19 efficient products and services. They have developed innovative approaches and have built on multiple levels of political Opportunities, such as those at the state level (Nadel, 2002: (Gillingham, Newell, and Palmer 2006). The process by which energy efficient products are introduced into the marketplace and over time diffuse and penetrate into the market in large numbers is known as market transformation. The strategies employed in market transformation include fimding research and development, conducting demonstrations and field tests, providing commercialization incentives, marketing and consumer education, grants loans and tax incentives, voluntary efficiency specification programs, bulk purchases, and mandatory standards (Geller and Nadel, 1994). These strategies are all aimed at producing changes in the markets for energy efficiency products though the philosophical basis of these strategies ranges from the policy tools of the command-and-control mandated standards to the economic tools of changing economic incentive structures to the marketing tools of branding and advertising. These activities have been carried out by a range of private, governmental, and nonprofit sector organizations, Often in intrasectoral and cross-sectoral coordination, to support the widespread market adoption of energy efficient appliances and building practices. Changes in the external sociopolitical conditions can only result in changes in the interorganizational network if they are perceived and acted upon at the organizational level. The dynamics that have emerged in energy efficiency resemble Meyer and Tarrow’s (1998:20) description of contemporary societies where contention “does not come from movement organizations as such but from campaigns organized by parties, interest groups, professional associations, citizens’ groups and public servants.” Social movement organizations are Often defined by their “non-institutional tactics” such as 20 protests (i.e. McAdam, 1982:25). However, energy efficiency organizations work within institutional boundaries through activities such as influencing policy with research and policy briefings, bringing lawsuits to force the government to establish energy efficiency standards while also pursuing market based solutions. Public protests are not part of their tactical repertoires. They are, however, all driven by the mission of improving energy efficiency. They are highly professionalized employing many technical and policy analysts. Only the few organizations that are related to environmentalism (such as Natural Resources Defense Council and Environmental Defense) have grassroots memberships as it has been noted that “energy efficiency” is not a “sexy” topic that the public has broadly mobilized around; though, in small geographical locations it has been a popular identity issue. I employ the term “energy efficiency nonprofit organizations” as it is theoretically neutral. I will investigate the ways they are like social movement organizations and the ways they are like interest groups. Non-profit energy advocates have cobbled together support from a range of elites with interests in energy efficiency. Organizations vary in the funding sources they pursue but potential funders include demand-side management programs run by electric utilities and others, progressive state energy Offices, foundations such as the Pew Charitable Trusts and the Energy Foundation, manufacturers, private for-profit energy efficiency service providers and consultants, the Environmental Protection Agency, and to a lesser extent the Department of Energy. Despite the similarities in organizational form, energy efficiency nonprofit organizations have maintained a high level of diversity in their discourses, tactics and partnerships undertaken in pursuing their energy efficiency goals. Organizations have 21 been formed at various levels of interests from national, regional, state, and local. They all wish to promote energy efficiency, but the ideal policies they would like to implement and the tactics they use to promote them are varied. Some are identified with the broader mainstream environmental movement, such as Natural Resources Defense Council, while others, though working towards a goal that could improve the environment, do not organizationally identify with the environmental movement. Like many environmental social movement organizations that are seeking to influence markets, they take the role of both adversaries and partners with corporations and the state (Galaskiewicz and Colman 2006). Some energy efficiency nonprofit organizations target the states and federal governments to regulate industry providing the underlying research for future efficiency standards and testifying and formally commenting on rulemakings. On several occasions lawsuits have been brought by nonprofits to force adoption of energy-efficiency product standards i.e. NRDC v. Herrington (1985). Other energy efficiency nonprofit organizations undertake more cooperative actions with states and industry such as providing third-party certification of energy-efficient products and joint marketing campaigns to promote efficient products. And some have undertaken both combative and cooperative actions over time, and even simultaneously. Differentiation in energy efficiency nonprofit organizations may be a result of differences in how they participate in and experience change processes in the organizational field including framing, institutional entrepreneurship, and network cultivation. By studying the mechanisms of change at the organizational level, I seek to understand how organizational factors influence these differences including the organizations overall position in the field, strong network ties such as board members and 22 funders, and an organization’s cultural and ideological orientation. For example, the collective framing of energy efficiency programs under the overall frame of market transformation is a cognitive mechanism of change that is inclusive of a range of organizational tactics that build on diverse opportunities to influence energy efficiency. From 1973 to 1987, the first advocacy nonprofit organizations engaging with the struggle over federal energy efliciency standards (mainly the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy and the Natural Resources Defense Council) saw little success on that front. However, Natural Resources Defense Council, and more specifically David Goldstein, senior scientist for their energy program and a former physics student of efficiency pioneer Arthur Rosenfeld began to adopt more innovative approaches to creating market supply and demand for energy efficient products. In the early 1990’s, Natural Resource Defense Council facilitated a commercialization effort for energy- efficient refi'igerators, called the Super Efficient Refrigerator Program. Twenty-five utilities across the U.S. pledge $30.7 million dollars of demand-side-management funding to Offer to the manufacturer of the most efficient refrigerator that met a set of specifications. Fourteen manufacturers submitted bids and Whirlpool won and went on to manufacture a refrigerator from 1993 to 1998. The halting of production of the model due to lack of sales has brought into the question whether the Super Efficient Refrigerator Program was a successful tactic, but the market based COOperative model of offering “carrots” has been a template for action for multiple other organizations. In 1993, the US Environmental Protection Agency created the voluntary Energy Star labeling program in response to the 1992 Energy Policy Act. The Energy Star initiative is a family of voluntary programs designed to increase energy efficiency and 23 reduce carbon emissions. EPA subsequently partnered with DOE in 1996 to promote the Energy Star label and broaden the range Of activities it covered. Over the past few years, Energy Star has expanded to cover 31 product categories, including residential and commercial buildings, residential heating and cooling equipment, major appliances, lighting, and consumer electronics. Cumulatively, by 2000 the Energy Star program had saved an estimated 1,130 petajoules (1015 joules) of primary energy and avoided the emission of an estimated 20.7 MIC of carbon (Webber, Brown, and Koomey 2000). The mission of the Energy Star program is to “realize significant reductions in emissions and energy consumption by permanently transforming markets for energy-consuming products” (Brown, Webber, and Koomey 2002). Demand side management programs that saw decreases in funding under deregulation in the late 1990’s also saw a resurgence, many Of them using Energy Star as a baseline level of energy efficiency to promote to commercial and residential energy end-users. There are several advantages to using the energy efficiency industry as a focus for my study. First, energy efficiency nonprofit organizations are diverse in the number and kinds Of ties they have developed with state and industry organizations. Second, organizations in the energy efficiency field have exhibited a good deal of innovation in the tactics they have used to cooperate with and coerce state and industry actors. Third, there are a number Of diverse interorganizational arrangements that have developed over time that aim to define and promote energy efficient products and services. Fourth, the relatively narrow focus on the specific issue of energy efficiency (versus energy or environmental policy more generally) enables me to identify a “whole-network” (Provan, Fish and Sydow, 2007) and study a broad range of organizational interactions at a high 24 level Of detail. And lastly, the recent evolution of the interorganizational network (post 1973) provides an Opportunity to follow up on the interorganizational analysis contained in this dissertation and conduct interviews with those who have been in the field since the beginning and have a historical perspective on how various external events were perceived and the organizational decision-making processes. Methods: Qualitative and Quantitative Network Approaches While environmental sociology predicts the environmental outcomes of societal power relations, and open systems theories of organizations predicts the behavioral implications of interorganizational relations, network theory provides us with an understanding and analytic approach for examining the organizational ties underpinning these theories. I construct a longitudinal data set of the various organizations that have participated in debates on the definition of energy efficiency from 1973 to 2006 and this data set is used to inform a network analysis. Comments, hearing transcripts, federal records, and agenda from these events aid me in the reconstruction of events and organizational participation in them. To construct this interorganizational data set, I utilize affiliation network data constructed from archival records of organizational participation in a broad range of events: 0 Department of Energy Minimum Standard Rulemakings for clothes washers, dishwashers, central air-conditioners, room air conditioners, and refrigerators/refrigerator-freezers (1980-2006) Interorganizational interactions during the Department of Energy’s federally regulated procedures for developing mandatory appliance minimum standards under the National Appliance Energy Conservation Act. The documents of record 25 includel) transcripts from hearings and workshops on standards with individuals and their organizational affiliation and 2) the submitted written comments on proposed standards in response to federal register notices. Environmental Protection Agency/ Department of Energy “Energy Star” Specification Development for clothes washers, dishwashers, central air- conditioners, room air conditioners, and refrigerators/refitgerator-freezers (1990- 2006) Interorganizational interactions of record during the development of the voluntary specifications used for the jointly run Environmental Protection Agency/ . Department of Energy “Energy Star” labeling program. The documents of record includel) meeting notes from Energy Star workshops and the individuals and organizational affiliations of those who participated and 2) submitted written comments that provide organizational stances on the development of Energy Star _ specifications. American Council for an energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE) Efficient Buildings Summer Study Conference (bi-annually 1980 to 2006) Interorganizational interactions during a bi-annual conference organized to bring technical and academic experts together with policy and other decision-makers to improve efficiency of buildings. Documents of record include individual and interorganizational affiliation for 1) registered participant of the conference 2) sponsor of the conference and 3) co-authorship of papers and papers topics for the conference. 26 American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE)/Consortium for Energy Efficiency Market Transformation Symposium (1997-2006) Annual conference in Washington DC focused on highlighting successful ongoing policies and practices promoting energy efficiency for policy makers, program planners, irnplementers and evaluators, manufacturers and trade allies in the field of market transformation. This also serves as the quarterly meeting of the Consortium of Energy Efficiency’s members. Documents Of record include the individual and organizational affiliation of 1) topics and presenters on the agenda and 2) registered attendees. Lawsuits regarding mandatory minimum energy efficiency standards (1973 — 2006) Interorganizational interactions in the judicial system regarding minimum energy efficiency standards under NAECA. Documents of record include the organizations bringing the lawsuit, those the lawsuit is brought against, and ancillary organizations involved. This data informs an understanding Of how the interorganizational network around energy efficiency has evolved over time. It specifically provides me with insights on the changes in the organizational populations that have participated in various kinds of events (lawsuits, congressional hearings, conferences) and the circumstances of these events. A full list of the events used in this study can be found in the Appendix A, Table There are some traditional concerns with affiliation data - mainly that they may not reflect actual relationships between organizations. However, I believe that such data 27 will prove usefiil in addressing my core questions. Many of the benefits of using affiliation data are derived from its duality (Breiger 1974; Field, Frank, Schiller, Riegle- Crumb, and Muller 2006). Linkages in an affiliation network occur between two different kinds of social entities: actors and events. The actors in this study are the organizations involved in defining and promoting energy-efficiency. The events are the testimonies, lawsuits, and meetings that bring these actors together regarding energy efficiency. In a sense, these events are “where the action is” in the contestation over energy efficiency]. Studying organizational affiliation networks is useful because they reflect how organizational strategic choice and constraints combine to create the formation of networks. The social constraints are determined by the events that are offered in society whilst the meaning of these events is determined by the set of organizations that attend it (Faust 2005). Affiliation networks can also be precursors to actual organizational relationships with each other and may provide insights into how these relationships form. The analysis of two-mode data tells you not only who is exposed to whom (the precursor of direct organizational relationships or one mode data) but exactly which events brought them together. I hypothesize that the introduction and socialization of organizations (such as learning about their mission and activities and the emergence Of tacit understandings) at these events is often an important part of the process of forming direct organizational partnerships. Finally, affiliation network data are beneficial in that they are a record of historical interactions and therefore particularly ' The use of these events is grounded in my three years of experience in the energy efficiency field and discussions with other actors working for energy efficiency advocacy organizations. While these events don’t capture every event that bring actors together, 1 would argue that these are the significant institutionalized events that occur on a regular basis. 28 useful in constructing longitudinal data sets. Such longitudinal data sets are essential for studying causal processes in network evolution. Dissertation Research Objectives As discussed earlier, my dissertation will examine interorganizational relations between business, government and non-profits in environmental and energy issues through three articles. The first article provides an analysis of the benefits of bringing insights from organizational and environmental sociology together and their potential to inform our understanding of climate change. This article summarizes five lessons that we can learn from these two fields and provides grounded examples of the insights gained fi'om each lesson using the issue of climate change. The second article examines the structure of relations between government, business and civil society organizations around energy efficiency from 1973 to 2007 and the external factors that influence that structure of relationships. Using data on the events discussed above, I propose a context- dependent theory of green consumer products. Building on treadmill of production and ecological modernization theory, I theorize the conditions under which the interorganizational power relations predicted by each would prevail. I support this approach to understanding the political economy of green consumer goods through a qualitative case study of the variations in the historical struggles between organizations to promote energy-efficient appliances. While the second article focuses on the external conditions of changes in the interorganizational network, the third article focuses on how energy efficiency organizational network embeddedness is related to organizational understandings of its sociopolitical environment and whether to work with businesses. This approach provides 29 insight on the underlying dynamics of the changing networks. To investigate this I ask whether an organization’s participation in events over time influences its subsequent actions to partner with business. This article builds on theories of institutional change to demonstrate how organizations make sense of changing political environments and who it is effective to partner with to pursue its goals. In answering these research questions, I expect the cumulative knowledge from these chapters to make some more general contributions to the study of cross-sectoral organizational relationships and the environment. First, through the aggregation of organizational populations upward to analyze sectoral relationships along with the analysis of individuals within the networks, I hope to encourage recognition of the importance of multi-level analysis in environmental issues and the use of organizations to develop meta-level understandings of macro-theories. Second, I intend this research to highlight the usefulness of examining cross-sectoral interorganizational networks through longitudinal network analysis as a means for more rigorous and systematic understanding of interactions of organizations over time. Finally, through the use of a range Of venues, regulatory and voluntary, state hosted and non-profit hosted, I hope to highlight the connections between these various mechanisms for defining energy efficiency and expand our current understanding of how we define policy networks from its narrow focus on regulatory venues Only. I expect this research to contribute to work on organizational network formation and institutional change in theories of environmental sociology. In addition, I hope that it will serve to inform future studies of formal organizations in energy and environmental sociology and the broader environmental social sciences. Further, these results will 30 contribute to an increased understanding of the environmental, economic, political and social contexts that influence the development and effectiveness of institutions for sustainability (as recommended by the National Research Council, 2005:47) and ultimately aid those nonprofit, business, and governmental organizations involved in building institutions for a healthy and sustainable environment. 31 CHAPTER ONE Strengthening Sociological Perspectives on Organizations and the Environment: Five Lessons from Organizational and Environmental Sociology Introduction Organizations have been described by Perrow (1997:66) as “the most intensive and effective environmental destroyer.” The social origins of many environmental problems and their solutions can be located within organizational and interorganizational processes. The organizations involved in these processes vary from informal to formal and private to public, including businesses, government agencies, and social movement organizations. Institutions like capitalism and the state may be the machines of environmental degradation, and individuals may make important decisions that impact the environment, but organizations are the cogs in the machines. Organizations bring institutional logics into everyday practice, providing the rules and cultural contexts for individual decisions about the environment. How individuals participate in organizations, and how organizations interact with other organizations, structures and influences many decisions that impact the environment. Climate change has been cited by scientists and politicians alike as one of the most pressing problems facing society today (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, 2007; Gore, 2006; Stern, 2006). At the root of climate change is the increase of greenhouse gas emissions (carbon dioxide, methane, some industrial compounds) that absorb infrared radiation from the sun and “trap” it in the earth’s atmosphere causing complex climatic changes. The 25% increase of greenhouse gases that scientists have 32 observed started about 150 years ago with the large scale industrialization that also brought the proliferation of formal organizations. Over the past twenty years approximately 75% of human caused greenhouse gas emissions are from the burning of fossil fuels for energy (U .8. Energy Information Administration, 2008). More than half the energy-related emissions come fiom large sources such as power plants and factories. Industrial processes (such as the production of cement, steel, and aluminum), agriculture, other land use, and waste management are also important sources of greenhouse gas emissions in the United States (Environmental Protection Agency 2008). The fossil fuel basis of the U.S. economy and social system means that all organizations utilize energy in its daily workings whether an office or a manufacturing plant. The recognition of the important role that formal organizations play in the production and mitigation of environmental problems such as climate change has led to a quickly growing multi and inter-disciplinary literature that focuses on the nexus of organizations and the natural environment. As the environment is increasingly recognized as a major social problem and prominent social theorists address it (Beck 1992; Luhmann 1989), the number of organizational sociologists that have undertaken studies of environmental issues has been growing (Bansal and Gao, 2006). In addition, business and public policy schools, where organizational sociologists are often trained and employed, have expanded their interests and programs in the environment (Finlay 1999). There also has been an increasing amount of work in environmental sociology at the organizational level and multiple environmental sociologists have suggested that more work on industries and organizations would be useful (Grant and Jones 2003; Grant, Jones, and Trautner 2004; Sonnenfeld and Mo] 2002). Considering the potential 33 for understanding how organizations contribute to environmental impacts and how the environment and natural resource issues impact organizations, it is surprising how little organizational and environmental sociologists studying similar issues have built on each other’s insights. Traditionally, environmental sociology has offered well developed theories of the macro political, economic and cultural factors influencing environmental degradation and reform along with more micro social psychological explanations of environmentalism. Environmental sociology has only engaged occasionally with the inspection of meta-level understandings of the role of organizational processes in environmental degradation and reform and the variation in these behaviors and outcomes. In contrast, organizational theory has developed a strong body of research on why and how organizations do what they do by theorizing both organizational and interorganizational processes, but often fall short of accounting for the larger political economic context of environmental issues and the extent of the material basis of organizations. Several reasons have been suggested for this failure to connect and integrate these two bodies of work. In his review of environmental sociology’s potential to inform research on business decision-making and the environment, Hoffman, an organizational sociologist who studies environmental issues, notes the tension between the “added value of creating distinct specialty fields (such as environmental sociology) versus remaining engaged with wider disciplinary approaches” (Hoffman 2005:211; Hoffman and Ventresca 2002:18). This criticism has also emerged fiom within environmental sociology. Gould, Pellow and Schnaiberg (2004:312) note that among environmental sociology’s weaknesses is “its failure to build lasting bridges to sociology itself.” In 34 addition, one may note that there are few occasions that organizational sociologists and environmental sociologists have the opportunity to interact. Butte] (2002) offers an opposing perspective, arguing that though the cost of the struggle to build the subdiscipline of environmental sociology was a temporary lack of engagement with other theoretical perspectives, the increasing strength of environmental sociology has yielded a growing number of productive engagements with broader sociological theoretical perspectives. I argue in this paper that synthetic lessons learned from environmental and organizational sociology could do much to advance a truly sociological perspective on organizations and the natural environment. No organization is an island — socially or ecologically In early classical organizational theory, organizations are conceptualized as closed rational systems. Weber’s theories on bureaucracy (1922) and Taylor’s scientific management (1916) view organizations as highly formalized rational collectivities pursuing agreed upon organizational goals. The organizational ideal was an isolated unit that served internal objectives and had no external resource dependencies. In this way, an organization was conceptualized as an island. An organization was separated fi'om the rest of the world with its workers carrying out only its organizational objectives set by those at the top of the organizational hierarchy. The resources needed to carry out those Objectives were owned by the organization, materializing within organizational boundaries as if appearing from nowhere. Subsequent organizational theory provided insights into just how unrealistic the ideal of the organization as an island is by highlighting the role of employees’ personal motivations, external resource dependencies, and external cultural pressures. 35 Despite realizing these external factors, the material and “natural resource” basis of organizations is still relatively ignored. That is, even with the rise of an environmental consciousness and the recognition of organizational impacts on the environment, the impact of the natural environment on organizations is relatively unexplored. A one way relationship where organizations impact the environment has developed rather than a conceptualization of the mutual dependencies. Organizational theories to date have not produced an integrative understanding of how organizations both influence and are influenced by the natural environment. If we think of power as “the ability of an individual or group (we shall call them A) to influence another individual or group (we shall call them B) in a non-trivial significant manner” (Cox, Furlong, and Page 1985:31) this challenge to organizational theory can be thought of as the failure to first, recognize the power of the natural environment and second, to understand the power relationship between organizations and the natural environment as a reciprocal relationship. Shrivastava (1994) attributes this failure of organizational studies to a narrow definition of organizational environment that focuses on the social environment at the cost Of the material environment. The raison d ’etre of environmental sociology is to bring to sociology an understanding of systems of human-environment relations as interdependent, entailing mutual influence, and dynamic, entailing change and stability. Asking why sociology as a whole had previously failed to address the natural environment, its relationship with humans, and problems of the deteriorating environment, Catton and Dunlap (1978) posited that sociology had been operating under the Human Exemptionalist Paradigm (HEP) - a belief that humans were unique from other species in their ability to develop 36 without limits. The assumptions of mainstream sociology about humans and their environment were questioned with the development of environmental sociology and the move towards the New Ecological Paradigm (NEP). NEP recognizes that humans may adapt and mitigate, but the assumption persists that humans are ecologically interdependent like all other species. In arguing for the “greening” of business studies, Gladwin, Kennelly, and Krause (1995) build on Catton and Dunlap’s work and contend that there must be a shift fiom the dominant social paradigm that does not account for the environment in the survival of social systems to one that recognizes human dependencies on the environment and integrates this into business studies. Similarly, Rosen and Sellers (1999) advocate eloquently for business historians to “. .. start asking explicit questions about the role of environmental factors in industrial development and corporate evolution in different places and times. More open-minded and empirical research will allow us to better determine how nature actually figured into what business managers did: how managers did or did not handle their firms' extraction and transformation Of natural resources; how nature's openings and impositions shaped their strategies and organizational choices.” They go on to argue that this focus can provide a corrective to overly cultural accounts Of business history. In this way, addressing the material basis of organizations will help bring about a re-merging of realist and constructivist approaches and provide the middle ground perspectives on the realist-constructivist debates that have emerged in environmental sociology to organizational studies (Kroll-Smith, Gunter, and Laska 2000; McLaughlin 2001; Rosa 1998) 37 Humans and their organizations are part of ecosystems and no organization is an island unto itself. Though organizations vary in the extent and character of their social and material connectedness they all are constrained by their social and material environment. NEP helps us to understand this by highlighting that earth has a finite level of natural resources and waste repositories and that the biophysical environment constrains human activity. It teaches us that organizations are not an island, and are not only connected with the social fabric fiom which they emerge, but have a mutual and dynamic connection with the natural environment. Understanding this helps us think about how organizations are intimately involved in the production of climate change while their daily Operations are inextricable from the climate system their activities are influencing. Climate assumptions are so interwoven into daily practices of organizations that the assumptions are often rendered invisible. Firms that have paid the most attention thus far are those directly connected to natural resources. For example, many industrial agricultural farms face shifts in geographical productivity. But less visible are all the organizations that utilize infrastructure with built in assumptions about climate. The Pew Center on Global Climate Change (Sussman and Freed 2008) issued a report that chronicles these threats such as the potential for extreme weather events to disrupt site work and impact worker health in the building and construction industry or the susceptibility of industries that use shipping in their supply chain. A recognition of the dual role of organizations in climate change as one that impacts climate and is impacted by climate highlights the need for a duality in responses by organizations. Climate change requires firms to undertake both mitigation Of their impacts to the climate system and adaptation of the way organizations do business. 38 Organizational environmental outcomes and their measurement matter While still struggling to come to grips with the natural resource basis of organizational life, research assessing the environmental impacts of organizations through both material and cultural indicators has gotten more attention. In fact, in their thorough review of management journal articles on organizations and the natural environment, Bansal and Gao found that more studies focused on reducing environmental impacts of organizations than organizational performance on other measures (such as profit). The measurement of organizational environmental impacts is a complex challenge facing all who seek to integrate social and natural variables in their studies. Bansal and Gao (2006) summarize the significant body of work documenting the links between organizations and the environment reporting that much of the research uses proxies of environmental performance. Some proxies of environmental performance utilize actual measurements of some material input or output such as toxic release reports and organizational waste generation and waste processing activities. Other proxies of environmental performance are reflections of how well an organization adheres to society’s expectations of what it means to perform environmentally, but do not actually attempt to measure the material outcomes. For example, an organization’s environmental performance has been measured via the amount of environmental litigation brought against it, the adoption of environmental management systems (such as ISO-14001), or other beyond compliance activities. In addition, some studies of organizational “greenness” have also been assessed by measuring the values, beliefs and attitudes of organizational members. 39 The imperative of undertaking these measurements in organization and environment studies is undeniable and yet we are well served by casting a critical eye to what we are actually measuring and its place in organizational and environmental processes. Some measures are indicators of the amount of stress being placed on the ecosystem while others measure the actual impact of the organization on an ecosystem. Impacts are the result of ecosystem responses to stressors and thus inherently more complicated. In addition, choosing specific indicators of environmental impacts may indicate improvement when environmental impacts have either been transformed in nature (i.e. a shift from using coal to nuclear) or across space and time. Take for example, the toxic release inventory (TRI). Grant, Bergesen, and Jones(2002) and Grant and Jones (2003) use toxic release inventories and find that large chemical plants emit toxins at a higher rate than small plants, and this difference increases if the large plant is part of a larger corporation. Freudenberg and colleagues (Fisher and Freudenburg; Freudenburg and Nowak 2000) use these same data to support the claim that there is a “disproportionality” between economic and environmental impacts at the level of economic sectors, industries, and specific facilities. These works are highly respectable in their efforts to integrate both social and natural variables. However, measures of toxic releases only consider pollution at the point of production, not the toxins in the end products. F urtherrnore, TRI only tracks certain chemicals that have been tested and determined to be toxic, while there is a large number of chemicals that have not been tested at all with some estimates assessing that only 10% of estimates have been tested. Assessments Of organizational “greenness” using measures other than actual environmental impacts need to be placed in context of how we understand organizational 40 decision-making and processes. Similar to the use of material measures, what is actually being measured should be carefully specified. We may imagine that an organization that has been involved in fewer environmental lawsuits is more environmentally responsible, or it may just be better at hiding environmental illegalities and harms. The use of adoption of environmental management systems or participation in voluntary green programs to assess environmental impact is based upon assumptions that this reflects a dedication to undertaking actions that actually decrease environmental impact. Whether this is true is a question for further research. Research evaluating voluntary programs has found that in general environmental behaviors and outcomes did not change with participation in a voluntary program, and that in some cases the environmental performance of firms actually decreased (deLeon and Rivera 2007; Dietz and Stern 2002). Similarly, one would theorize that possession of environmental attitudes about business sustainability by organizational members would be reflected in environmental decision-making and thus improved environmental performance. However, we know from research on individuals that pro-environmental attitudes and beliefs do not always translate to pro-environmental actions, often due to constraints in the choices individuals face (Gardner and Stern 1995; Kollmuss and Agyeman 2002; Tanner 1999). All this demonstrates the challenges of developing measures and the need to be explicit about what is and is not being measured. The further development of organizational environmental outcome measurements within an integrated understanding of organizational resource processes is a worthy goal for both environmental and organizational sociologists. 41 Developing models of greenhouse gas footprints Of organizations is thus an important step in assessing impacts of organizational and interorganizational characteristics and impacts. The literature from industrial ecology and material flows provides us one basis for calculating the material usage of organizations. An obvious proxy is energy use though we must also remember that there are other greenhouse gases in addition to carbon dioxide (such as methane). Lough (1996) provides an insightful discussion of the amount of energy needed to maintain industrial society’s structure and reports findings on six organizations, their organizational characteristics and energy use. Lough’s findings confirm earlier studies of energy use and organizational structure. Organizations that were smaller, part of the private sector, and part of the service sector were more energy-efficient than their counterparts that were larger, in the public sector or manufacturing sector. Corporate environmental actions vary and are context-dependent Two major theories in environmental sociology that are used to make sense of the capitalist system’s role in environmental problems and solutions are treadmill of production (Schnaiberg, 1984) and ecological modernization (M01 and Spaargaren, 2000). Treadmill of production (TOP) generally views capitalist organizations as following the logics set out by the capitalist system in that it will act as an economic rational actor maximizing profit by pursing the cheapest resource extraction and waste disposal methods that it can legally get away with (Gould and Gould 1994). Variations in this behavior are therefore due to variations in economic conditions facing firms. Meanwhile, ecological modernization (EMT) suggests that further development of capitalism and the state regulation and public pressure it brings will lead to capitalist 42 organizations adopting a broader more ecological and economic perspective on decision- making. EMT sees the firm and markets as more socially embedded, perceiving and responding to cultural and economic cues. Those who have studied a number individual firms and environmental decision- making have probably seen both theories at work. Organizational researchers and theorists from all perspectives have undertaken a large variety of work to investigate the sources Of the variation of corporate decision-making on the environment. There is research that supports that the level of homogeneity and heterogeneity in environmental corporate behavior across industries varies. Some industries have undertaken reactive pro-environmental behaviors in a united fashion. For example, the chemical industry responded to its deadly plant explosion in Bhopal by self-regulating through the Responsible Care Program (Hoffman, 1999). On the other hand, some industries have acted in unity to resist the adoption of pro-environmental behaviors. The oil industry’s initial response to climate change was to form the Global Climate Coalition and link to conservative think tanks to contest that climate change was a problem (McCright and Dunlap 2000). However, the oil industry’s initial response to climate change has been followed by a disintegration of unity as corporations took a variety of stances (Pulver 2007; van den Hove, Le Menestrel, and de Bettignies 2002). Similarly, Levy and Rothenberg (2002) provide an account of the diversity in responsiveness to climate change in the automobile industry. Understanding the factors that influence organizational decision-making towards environmental disasters or improved environmental outcomes is an essential contribution that organizational and environmental sociology can offer to the study of humans and the 43 environment. Dietz and Henry (2008) point out that Hardin’s theory of the tragedy of the commons, where resources are exploited by individuals to the point of collapse, is based on the assumptions of narrow self-interest embodied in the rational actor paradigm. Indeed, if a firm is in full adherence with the economic rational actor paradigm then it will use and dispose of resources in the least costly ways possible, maximizing profit and most likely simultaneously maximizing harm to the environment. A central question for the social sciences is then to assess what factors drive resource decision-making (Dietz 2005; Dietz and Henry 2008). Under what conditions do narrow self interests prevail and when are broader societal interests accounted for? In regards to the capitalist firm, under what contexts do firms account for the health of the environment and resources and take action accordingly? Dietz and Henry provide three understandings of how context matters in environmental decision-making. First, context can be understood as how the state of one variable is related to the state Of another variable. For example, Prakash and Potoski (2007) propose that organizational decisions to participate in a voluntary environmental program are dependent upon the ability to make benefits of green club membership excludable (the Olsonian dilemma) and the potential the members will shirk their responsibility to meet club standards thus jeopardizing potential benefits to all members. The second understanding of context is “the larger landscapes of local and national govermnent and the local, regional, and global political economies that shape actions and responses to actions” (Dietz and Henry, 2008:13190). For example, theories of political economy Of the environment in environmental sociology suggest that governmental resource management decisions will favor business interests because the government is 44 dependent upon business profits for a tax base (O'Connor 1973; Schnaiberg 1980). The third understanding of context is the social relationships or network in which decision- making is embedded. Pulver (2007) illustrates how oil companies made divergent assessments of the market risks and opportunities related to climate change because of the different scientific and policy networks they were embedded in, rather than rational economic criteria. Stern and Barley (1996: 154) similarly argue that the organizational research community can provide a corrective to law and economics “overly rational and coercive mechanisms” for understanding environmental issues. In organizational sociology, theories have constantly evolved to try to provide a realistic account of how decision- making takes place and the importance of context. Scott describes the most recent wave of theories as an open system perspective. These theories view organizational actions as being embedded in broader environments. Open systems theories include Harman and Freeman’s (1977) organizational ecology model, Pfeffer and Salancik’s (1978) resource dependence model, and Meyer and Rowan’s institutional theory (1977; DiMaggio and Powell, 1983). At the heart of all these perspectives is the question of what motivates organizational behavior and decision-making. One area where these theories have been used to understand when organizations undertake actions beyond their narrowly defined interests is the study of corporate environmentalism. A great deal of this work is engaged with explaining the development of corporate environmentalism, when firms or industries take pro-environmental action beyond regulatory demands. Business decisions about resource use and conservation have Often been understood as a rational organization pursuing the defined goal of profit. A strong 45 case has been made that acting on environmental issues such as climate change accomplishes the business goal of profit maximization through improved reputation and increased legitimacy, decreased government regulation, long term economic goals, decreased risk of liability, and production cost savings among others (Aupperle, Carroll, and Hatfield 1985; Burke and Logsdon 1996; Hoffman 2006b). Lyon and Maxwell (2004) expand this approach to utilize economic tools to model the political economy of corporate environmentalism. Their contention is that cost reductions from eco-efficiency and increases of market demand from green consumers are only modest influencers of corporate environmental action and the real driver is the state and public policy. Using a policy life cycle approach they demonstrate that once an issue has the potential to be regulated the costs to firms increase with time: voluntary actions that preempt new laws have the lowest impact on firms, trying to influence regulations has a greater impact on firms, and deflecting enforcement at the end of the policy life cycle has the highest impact on firms. Lyon and Maxwell’s work provides insights on understanding variations across industries but, like much of the rational system work, is limited when faced with variation between firms that face relatively similar external pressures but exhibit variations in environmental behaviors. To explain this variation, some organizational theorists have adopted an approach to organizational decision-making that focuses on internal decision- making factors. Supported by empirical research on environmental decisions in businesses, Bansal and Roth have argued for a mixed motives theory of environmental decision-making where organizations are seeking to fulfill multiple objectives (Bansal and Roth 2000). For example, Dutton et a1. (1997) found that the perception Of how 46 important an issue is has been found to be related to how well it fits with the organizational and top leadership values and concerns rather than any “rational” strategic imperative. Meyerson’s (2003) research on “tempered radicals” has found that some individuals will champion social initiatives in the workplace (i.e. environmental, affirmative action, fair trade) because they are personally important to them. Management’s receptivity to undertaking an environmental initiative is also influenced by their personal values (Bansal 2003). These theories highlight the embeddedness of individuals in both organizational cultures but also broader society. With the rise of environmentalism as a popular movement, it is more and more likely that individuals will hold these attitudes and bring them into new institutional contexts and the potential for social movements to have impacts this way has been highlighted in Zald’s work on “ideologically structured action” (Zald 2000). Others have turned further outward to explain firm and industry variations in environmental behavior. Open system theories are gaining recognition across fields in sociology for understanding the constitution of organizational life and provide the most insight into the context dependencies of organizational decision-making on the environment. Both resource dependence and new institutionalism saw the social context and organizational environment in which an organization was embedded as a key influence in organizational behavior. Resource dependence focused on the external factors organizations need to control to achieve their goals. It therefore theorizes organizations as seeking power and exercising it strategically (or rationally) to gain control of those organizational resources needed to achieve its goals and open up space for actions that reach its organizational Objectives. New institutional theory differed in 47 focusing on the irrationalities of organizational life and focusing more on the role of cultural norms. Organizational actions are often less a result of deliberate strategic action than the result of people in organizations following scripts or templates for behavior provided by those around them. This can result in what Powell and Dimaggio (1983) refer to as organizational isomorphism where organizations tend toward similar forms and behaviors. Many theoretical advances have been made to merge these two perspectives towards providing an account of embedded rational organizational decision- making where opportunities and constraints for strategic choice are embedded within the institutional environment. Organizations may act strategically from this situated understanding Of rational action (Clemens 1997; Greenwood and Hinings 1996). Beamish (2001; 2002) builds on the internal sense-making processes of organizations in perceiving and reacting to the external environment to provide an explanation of how organizational processes can lead to non-action regarding the prevention and management of environmental risks by undertaking a study of the Guadalupe Dunes Oil Spill in California. Beamish focuses on the material characteristics of the environmental crisis in this case, a “crescive crisis” where the impacts are more insidious over long periods of time. Examples of this are an oil spill underground (such as the Gaudalupe Dunes) or climate change. Beamish’s study focuses on how the oil company, state and public involved interpreted whether the spill was problematic and highlights the role that organizational routine plays in failure to recognize the risks of environmental degradation. Oliver (2008) extends this work to how these organizational processes in remedying one environmental risk can lead to the creation of new risks. 48 The implicit acceptance and routinization of environmental behaviors and how these norms are transformed is taken up by new institutional theorists. Bansal and Gao (2006:463) conclude that “the new institutional analysis has been the dominant theoretical theme among studies with a natural environment context, likely because institutional forces have such a significant role in environmental issues.” While DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983) characterization of organizational isomorphism suggests that organizations become increasingly homogenous in structure, beliefs, and actions to increase organizational legitimacy, those working in this area have also paid close attention to the sources of heterogeneity in firm behavior and performance. Bansal and Clelland (2004) analyzed media reports and stock prices of 100 firms over a five-year period and found that environmentally legitimate firms had less stock market risk than illegitimate firms. Environmental legitimacy is determined by the extent that firms conform to stakeholders' expectations regarding environmental management. The analysis also showed that firms with low environmental legitimacy could reduce their risk by expressing commitment to the natural environment. Pulver (2007) argues that differences in networks and embeddedness of oil companies led to differing interpretations and stances on climate change. Prakash and Potoski’s (2006:41) study organizational participation in voluntary environmental programs (termed “green clubs”) through combining what they call rational-choice institutionalism where actors seek to maximize their net benefits with new institutionalism where “actors respond to the logic of appropriateness choosing the course of action that seems most normatively appropriate.” They contend that organizational decisions to participate in voluntary environmental programs are dependent upon the design of the program. To encourage 49 participation a program must be designed so that the benefits of green club membership are excludable and the program design must minimize the risk that members will shirk their responsibility to meet club standards thus jeopardizing potential benefits to all members. The total body of this work suggests that the likelihood of voluntary corporate action to protect the environment is an interaction between three conditions 1) the external organizational environment that makes pro-environmental action necessary, desirable, and legitimate 2) the organization’s competitive position in that environment and 3) the internal organizational members’ ability to perceive financial and external pressures to act voluntarily and frame environmental action as an Opportunity for improving organizational survival. A firm is highly unlikely to act if it 1) would actually lose competitive advantage, 2) faces little or none external pressure from its organizational and institutional environment and 3) has no internal champion for the action. The stronger the presence of each one of these conditions is, the more likely voluntary pro-environmental action is to occur. This lesson teaches us that encouraging corporate action on climate change should proceed with multiple approaches that provide these enabling conditions. Regulations and market-based programs should seek to align incentives so that action maintains market competitiveness. Programs that expose organizations to the business logic behind climate change action and provide models for emulation of respected organizations that have taken successful climate change actions can change the networks organizations are embedded in and the information transmitted. These programs can also provide internal champions with the tools they need to make the case for action. 50 Cooperation and cooptation are two sides of the same coin Organizational studies focusing on networks, particularly in governance, have focused on the benefits of new public-private partnerships between organizations (Huxharn 1996). The development of new cooperative actions between environmental, governmental and corporate organizations is often offered as a pathway to increasing sustainability pointing to the need for increased flexibility and innovation to address the complex problems Of non-point source pollution and global climate change (Berenbaum 1999; Wondolleck and Yaffee 2000). Paralleling this reasoning, in environmental sociology, ecological modernization theory suggests that more direct negotiations between environmental social movement organizations and business will produce more innovative “win-win” solutions using the market (M01 1995; Spaargaren 1997). The enthusiasm for these approaches leaves O’Toole and Meier (2004) warning of the dark side of interorganizational networks and “desperately seeking Selznick.” Selznick’s (1966) treatise on the Tennessee Valley Authority brought to light the problem of cooptation and serves as a founding literature for the future development of resource dependence theory. He identifies cooptation as when an organization absorbs new elements into its policy-deterrnining structure to avert threats to its stability or existence. Formal cooptation occurs when an organization faces a crisis of legitimacy and integrates outside interests formally and publicly, while informal cooptation is where organized forces that are in a position to enforce demands are given a role in policy determination, but explicit recognition of this position is avoided to sustain legitimacy. Cooptation will result in changes in the character and role of organizations. 51 Environmental sociology’s theories provide perspective on the broader political and economic environment for these partnerships. Treadmill of production and ecological modernization propose a role for the environmental movement, though each varies in its understanding of environmental social movement power in relation to the state and corporations. Buttel (2004:331) characterizes the treadmill of production perspective as early on considering environmentalism as a “crucial force that is subject to trivialization” while later theorizations still claimed it to be crucial but “overwhelmed by transnational and local treadmills and undermined by commodification.” In treadmill of production, because of the concentration of capital within corporations, social movements are particularly susceptible to cooptation because of their limited monetary resources. Treadmill of production sees these interactions through the lens of resource dependence. In ecological modernization, the environmental movement is seen as having more power in being able to institutionalize ecological objectives through motivation of public pressures and state regulation. Ecological modernizationists see these collaborations through the lens of new institutional theory — organizational objectives are aligning as corporations adopt ecological logics. Sonnenfeld (2002) poses a series of questions about social movements and the political processes of ecological modernization including whether social movements have: 1) moved from radical opposition to capitalism, industrialization and bureaucratization, to greater involvement in environmental reform efforts, 2) become more single-issue oriented, rather than remaining part of broader social movements, 3) shifted from being “outside influences” to becoming “inside” players in environmental transformation, 4) played an increasingly direct role in planning and designing new production technologies, and 5) shifted from working with the state to 52 working more closely with market actors. While these questions are to assess the extent Of the ecological modernization process, these are the same questions that are Often asked by those who are assessing the cooptation of the environmental movement. Whether an organization has made a reasonable compromise in cooperation to meet mutual goals or whether it has been coopted by the partner organization is a difficult judgment. In other words, all interorganizational relationships involve cooperation and cooptation to the extent that they all require compromise. Though labeling specific organizational partnerships as compromise or cooptation is perhaps a subjective and unproductive process, there are multiple opportunities to investigate the dynamics of cooperation and cooptation and their outcomes in public- private environmental partnerships. The productive collaboration between organizational sociology and social movement theory is one place where scholars can build this study. Introducing a special issue of Mobilization, Caniglia and Carmin (2005) articulate that social movement organizations should be studied in their own right and that the clear way to accomplish this is to link social movement theories (such as resource mobilization, political process, and framing) to organizational theories (such as resource dependence and new institutionalism). This conversation has produced a book (McAdam, Scott, Davis, and Zald 2005) that highlights the similarities and differences in the theories and points to how social movement theory can benefit from organizational understandings of processes and outcomes and how business organizations may be understood through the lens of social movements (Berg and Zald, 1978; Morrill, Zald and Rao, 2003; Davis and McAdam, 2000). 53 Much of the research conducted in environmental sociology on environmental social movement organizations (ESMOs) has touched upon the impacts of interorganizational relations. This has Often focused on the capabilities and selection of tactics in populations of environmental organizations with a critical eye on the institutionalization and cooptation of the movement. Mitchell (1979) led the way in focusing on organizations in the U.S. environmental movement in his analysis of large national organizations making up the environmental lobby. He focused on the institutional tactics, such as litigation and lobbying, undertaken by organizations like Natural Resources Defense Council and Sierra Club and their successful use of mail campaigns. Brulle (2000) identifies the organizational environmental movement using a database of U.S. environmental organizations (as registered as tax-exempt organizations with the IRS) to analyze why the U.S. environmental movement has not attained the levels of social change seen in other nations. He concludes that organizational capacities for social learning as needed for communicative action are limited by the organizational characteristics found within the environmental movement: 1) competing and disparate organizational discourses between organizations and a lack Of an turifying frame, 2) movement organization ties to business and foundations that result in cooptation, and 3) external ties facilitate need for centralized management, professionalization, and mass mailings that limit democratic participation in organizations. These conclusions are supported by Mertig, Dunlap and Morrison’s findings as well (2002). More recently Brulle and Jenkins and colleagues have continued this focus on studying environmental movement organizations in relation to the strength of civil society and the impacts of foundation funding (Brulle and Jenkins 2005; Brulle and Jenkins 2006). 54 Many researchers studying populations of environmental movement organizations have utilized approaches from organizational ecology to undertake studies of the organizational populations of environmental movement organizations. McLaughlin and Khawaja (2000) use organizational ecology and resource mobilization theory to explain national population dynamics of the U.S. environmental movement. Andrews and Edwards (2005) examine the structures of local organizations in North Carolina and how various organizational characteristics, such as geographic scope, degree of professionalization, and tactical repertoires are related to each other. On a more global scale, Murphy (2005) uses organizational ecology to analyze the population of transnational environmental movement organizations (TNESMOS) and finds that the increasing number of coalition organizations decreases the number of foundings of new organizations. Ties between TNESMOS are studied in relation to ties with international governmental organizations in Caniglia’s (2001) analysis of the flow of information between these organizations, while Lewis (2000) documented the factors that impacted TMESMO’s decisions to firnd debt-for-nature swaps in developing nations. In addition to studies of organizational populations, there have been multiple studies that have looked at individual cases or organizations. Pellow (2001), who works in the political economic tradition, utilizes a comparative case study approach to update political process theory and its relevance to environmental justice. Analyzing two cases of movement, governmental, and corporate organizational interactions over the siting of two toxic sites, he suggests that environmental movement organizations that recognize the weakening of state power and strengthening of corporate power and adjust their tactics accordingly are more likely to succeed. In their study of Friends of the Earth and 55 Greenpeace, two organizations with no corporate ties, Carmin and Balser (2002)explicitly utilize cognitive organizational perspectives on sense-making and merge these with Tilly’s concept of organizational repertoires Of collective actions. They find that experience, core values and beliefs, environmental philosophy and political ideology work together to create organizational interpretations of the political environment and tactical efficacy. Organizational and environmental sociology have much to contribute to understanding the relationships between ESMOs, corporations, and the state. Resource dependence and new institutional theory provide an understanding of how interorganizational relationships are formed and the expected impacts of those relationships. Environmental sociology provides us with an understanding of the broader institutional context of the relationship between social movements, the state, and corporations under capitalism. Future investigations should examine what kinds of relationship between ESMOs and the state/corporations lead to cooptation. Longitudinal studies of organizations with data on tie formations and dissolutions along with organizational outcomes can provide insight into the organizational impacts of the relationships. Hoffman (2006a) has begun this undertaking by examining interlocking boards of non-profit environmental organizations and environmental organization website links to corporations and organizational activities and perceptions of these organizations. What are the impacts of these ties and what kinds of ties between social movement organizations and others make a difference in subsequent behavior (funding, joint efforts, engaging in meetings together)? What kinds of ties enable an organization to reach its 56 original goals with little impact? How can ESMO’s heed Selznick’s advice (l965:v) to “guard against organizational surrender” when making needed compromises? The cumulative environmental impacts of organizational change are constrained by system tendencies Much has been written about the potential for greening capitalism (O’Connor, 1994). Allan Schnaiberg’s (1980) breakthrough political economic analysis of environmental problems and subsequent work on the treadmill of production (TOP) builds on the Monthly Review school of Marxism and theorizes that the institutional arrangements under monopoly capitalism result in the competition and concentration of capital that leads to increases in capital investment and technological efficiency. These conditions result in the increasing rates of withdrawals of material resources from the earth and additions Of these material resources transformed into waste and deposited into the environment. This cycle is referred to as the treadmill of production. Subsequent to TOP’s initial publication, Schnaiberg and Gould (1994) wrote a chapter that made explicit their understanding of economic organizations. Business organizations are assumed to have singular decision-making criteria as reflected in a rule-based rational systems approach. As these business organizations are situated within capitalist institutions these criteria are driven by capitalist logics such as profit-maximization. Under TOP theory, firms arrive at the conclusion that the best return on this accumulated capital is the investment in more capital and technological efficiency. This predicts that firms all make similar decisions regardless of the internal dynamics of the firm as natural systems perspectives would suggest. Schnaiberg and Gould state that social, economic, and political forces outside the firm (such as the state or social movements) may alter 57 behavior, but that all firms will resist and try to suppress these forces. As Pulver (2007:49) summarizes “from a treadmill perspective, firm-level activities cannot change system-level dynamics.” In ecological modernization theory, M01 and Spaargaren argue that a reflexive ecological consciousness will result in a new politics and transformation of industrial practices and technological innovation that will benefit the environment (Spaargaren, 1997). This model is rooted in an economic model of change with social implications, deriving its basis from earlier work done by resource economists on internalizing the externalities of markets. In this economic model, businesses face increasing costs of resources from both increasing scarcity and increased state-irnposed costs on resource withdrawals and resulting pollution outputs. In accounting for these increased costs of resource use and by-products, firms respond by investing in technologies that reduce resource use. Ecological modernization clearly emphasizes a firm’s ability to perceive changing external conditions like environmental destruction and increasing costs of resources and react by altering their use of resources in response. One underlying difference between treadmill of production and ecological modernization theory is the level agency granted to corporations and industrial sectors in being able to react to their external environment and seek to alter it. Ecological modernization also provides for more variation in behaviors between organizations and industries, rather than the view of a united group of economic organizations. In addition, in ecological modernization theory economic organizations do not necessarily resist changes from environmental influences such as social movements and the state, and in fact, interorganizational 58 partnerships between these groups are highlighted as part of the process Of political modernization. As discussed in the section on corporate environmentalism, at both the corporate and industry levels we see corporations undertaking environmental actions characterized by ecological modernization. Pulver (2007) suggests that understanding variations in firm environmental behavior is a necessary step of understanding eventual broader tendencies in capitalism. Pulver employs new institutionalist models of firm behavior to focus on bottom up organizational processes in the interpretation of contestation of what is economically profitable and environmentally desirable. This perspective on social embeddedness and interpretation of environmental conditions provides useful understanding on how firms come to make certain decisions. However, as we as sociologists proceed in undertaking these organizational and sectoral studies it is important to simultaneously understand the broader system that serves as the context Of these actions and the material constraints to them. There are clearly a number of stances and actions a corporation can take. However, corporate decisions are bound by the logic of capitalism. Most obviously, we know this because any organization that alters its organizational objectives to pursue environmental objectives at the cost of its profit objectives will cease to exist. Perrow’s (1999) understanding of “normal accidents” in high-risk technologies is another theory that identifies how system structure can continue to produce environmental disorganization despite individual organizational changes. Studying systems like nuclear power facilities, chemical and petroleum refineries, and aircraft operations, Perrow “locates the risks associated with these complex technical systems in 59 organizational configurations rather than operational error.” (Beamish, 2002:46). He identifies how interactively complex systems have the potential to interact in so many ways that it is nearly impossible for humans to calculate all the interactions and plan for them. Tightly coupled systems compound this challenge by increasing the time dependence of events in a system creating little slack for adjustment. The result is that, though of low probability, high magnitude accidents are almost an inevitable and part of the system. Understanding the limits to greening business organizations and technological advancements has important implications for our responses for mitigating and adapting to climate change. Consider the case Of meeting current and future electricity needs. “Normal accidents” in tightly coupled technological systems means that simply switching energy sources will continue to leave us susceptible to energy and ecological disruptions. The theory of normal accidents instead suggests that a de-centralized decoupled energy system where small scale renewable energy technologies and efficiency could help us mitigate climate change while also helping us avoid low risk high impact disasters. Treadmill of production theory provides insights into why this kind of de-centralized energy system is unlikely to prevail as one of the solutions to mitigating climate change. Schnaiberg (1994) writes on the appropriate technology movement of the late 1960’s and 1970’s and its advocacy for the local development of small scale energy systems and how the political economy of energy led to the adoption of energy policies that instead favored large scale technologies that supported the status quo. We can witness this currently as nuclear re-emerges as a climate change solution. The lessons of “normal accidents” and 60 the political economy of energy policy are instructive as social science research seeks to inform our transition to decreasing fossil fuel use. Those who attend to the limits of reform and system tendencies are often accused of being pessimists. It is depressing to point out a switch fiom fossils to solar includes the growth of the manufacturing Of solar technologies that involves increased mining and creation of toxic by products. However, we may take inspiration from Selznick (1966). After being charged with embracing a “pathos of pessimism” by Gouldner, Selznick (1966:v) wrote about the obligation of research to critically assess our ability to meet ideals: The point Of anti-utopian criticism is not that it denigrates ideas. Rather it asks that such ideals [sic] be given their proper place in human affairs. Ideals are definers of aspiration. They are judgments upon us. But they are not surrogates for operative goals. The latter have the special virtue, and suffer the peculiar hardship, of striving to be reasonably adequate renderings of the moral ideal while taking due account of the human condition of the historical setting. A practical goal that does not rise to Opportunities is unworthy; but one that ignores limitations invites its own corruption. To ignore the challenges to sustainability - to systematically focus narrowly on an organization, a firm, a nation, without considering the larger context - is a disservice to the discipline Of sociology, the public, and the environment. Conclusion 61 The need for a truly sociological perspective on organizations and the natural environment is critical to understanding and solving environmental problems. In this article, I have tried to illustrate how bringing research and theory in organizational and environmental sociology together can provide a stronger and more balanced sociological perspective on the roots of and solutions for environmental problems. Taken together, these subdisciplines can help sociological research on organizations and environment toward the ideal of integrating the social/cultural and natural/material dynamics of organizations by recognizing the material basis of organizational life and its impacts. In addition, research on business decision-making and the natural environment united with an understanding of its political economy provides insights into the contexts of pro- environmental and harmful actions toward the environment. Finally, work from each subdiscipline also provides balance on the dangers of and potentials for public-private cooperation on environmental issues and the potential for and limits to change within systems. I hope that this article provides an impetus for organizational and environmental sociologists working on these issues to read each others’ work, talk at conferences, and maybe even enjoy a meal together. There are surely more lessons to be learned together. 62 CHAPTER TWO A Context-Dependent Theory of Green Consumer Goods: Conditions of Dynamic Power Relations in the Struggle for Energy Efficient Appliances Introduction For the past decade, environmental sociologists have wrestled with making sense of the current state of U.S. environmental politics through the use of two major theoretical lenses: treadmill of production (TOP) theory and ecological modernization theory (EMT). TOP theory emphasizes the structure of capitalism and its intrinsic acceleration of resource use and misuse while EMT focuses on the potential for modern capitalist societies to transform industrial structure and production to improve resource use. Both perspectives have been able to point to cases that support their theoretical argument (Pellow, Weinberg & Schnaiberg, 2000; Sonnenfeld, 2000; Scheinberg 2003). Almost all have agreed that each theory can account for the experiences of specific nations or industries at certain times, indicating that the underlying historical social and economic conditions assumed in each theory make them context-dependent (Buttel and Gijswijt 2000; M01 and Spaargaren 2000). In this article, I specify the sociopolitical factors likely to result in the power relations underlying each theory. I then analyze the case of U.S. state, business, and social movement efforts to define and promote residential energy efficiency from 1973 to 2006. I use this case to analyze how and when the state-business-social movement relations underlying EMT or TOP predictions have prevailed and illustrate the potential value for this contextual approach. 63 The context dependent focus used here to explore these political economic theories of the environment is inspired by Hooks’ (1993) political sociology approach to investigating competing theories of the state. Heeding Merton’s (1968) call for middle range theory, Hooks (1993:75) argued that the strong versions of theories of the state made “a priori commitments that only the converted would endorse.” Weaker variants relaxed the strong assumptions acknowledging limits of theories and used pieces of each theory to explain phenomenon in an ad-hoc fashion. This allowed the weakened theoretical formulations to account for more of the complexities of history, but also caused them to become less theoretically distinctive. Indeed, I believe this is the very situation that environmental sociologists face today in working to assess the political economic forces of environmental degradation and reform. In this paper, I propose to lay the groundwork for a theory that more fully accounts for both environmental degradation and improvement by scoping the sociopolitical conditions of TOP and EMT. This contextualized political economic theory of green consumer products is then applied to examine the conditions of evolving institutional relationships among the state, business and social movements and their outcomes around the definition and promotion of energy efficient residential appliances. The 1973 oil shock shook American’s sensibilities about energy use. Until that point, policymakers and economists assumed that if there was a demand by household consumers for an energy-efficient appliance, companies would respond by developing efficient appliance technologies for the market. The “invisible hand” of the market would work so that supply met the emerging demand and there was no need for public policy actions. However, facing rising input fuel costs and increased opposition to and regulation of siting electricity plants, electric utilities 64 managers and public policymakers realized that increasing the supply of electricity would become more expensive, while continuing low prices through government regulation provided no market incentive for household consumers to want efficient products. One environmentally-friendly way to meet the increasing U.S. energy needs was to improve the efficiency of residential appliances. This case focuses on the societal struggle to empower residential energy consumers to save energy and money by improving the efficiency of residential appliances for consumers. I find that a high threat of regulation of manufacturers is a major driver of business’s willingness to cooperate with social movement organizations. High threat of regulation occurs under conditions where the state is open to environmental movement influence, the presence of environmental crisis, and high levels of environmental awareness and support. The conditions that result in a low threat of regulation are high business unity, economic crisis, and low levels of political opportunity for environmental movement influence. Under conditions that lead to a low threat of regulation, the power relations described by TOP prevail and business interests dominate environmental issues. Under conditions that result in a high threat of regulation, the power relations described by EMT prevail. Standing alone, neither can explain the variations in the relationships among state, business and social movements around environmental issues. However, brought together by specifying the conditions under which each prevails, the theory can explain efforts to improve energy efficiency under certain conditions. Current Limits to Understanding Environmental Degradation and Improvement The strong variants of EMT and TOP are broad macro-level theories of the state, business, and social movements that explain the extent of environmental degradation or 65 improvement in modern capitalist societies. As is, these theories are difficult to support, and efforts to evaluate them have consisted mainly Of a single nation or industry leading to problems of case selection.2 In addition, even empirical work on the same industry, urban recycling, has led different researchers to different conclusions about the meaning Of events and the ecological outcomes (Pellow, Weinberg & Schnaiberg, 2000; Weinberg, Pellow & Schnaiberg, 2000; Scheinberg, 2003). Despite advocacy for more well-constructed empirical research to shed light on this debate, work that contextualizes these theories and views them as on-going processes in time and space continues to be lacking (York, Rosa, and Dietz Forthcoming 2008). In this paper, I will develop a context dependent theorization of green consumer products that integrates both theories through a longitudinal case study of the dynamic power relations of efforts within the U.S. to improve the efficiency of home appliances. The strong variant of ecological modernization states that the Objectives Of business, the state, and civil society align to account for both economic and ecological values in decision-making. EMT describes this process Of one where the economy is ecologized and ecology is economized through the modernization of production and consumption processes (M01, 1995; Spaargaren, 1997; M01 and Spaargaren, 2000). Environmental problems are a result of the failure of capitalism and accompanying political institutions to modernize enough to bring about the technological solutions that result from a merging of ecological and economic objectives. In EMT, public pressure and market regulation are strong enough forces to lead corporate actors to incorporate ecological rationales into their decision-making, effectively greening capitalism. As this 2 For an exception see York, R., E. A. Rosa, and T. Dietz. 2003. "Footprints on the earth: The environmental consequences of modernity." American sociological review 68:279-300. 66 process occurs, EMT predicts that businesses participate in leading this ecological restructuring by taking pro-environmental actions beyond those required by regulation. State agencies focus on facilitating business leadership through a shift away from command-and-control regulation and toward more inclusive negotiated rule-makings and flexible approaches. Environmental social movement organizations adopt new tactics in moving these goals forward by engaging in direct cooperative partnerships with businesses (M01 1995). Intensifying relationships among these groups are indicative of the shared logics of “greening” the economy and development of cooperative working relationships to reach these goals. This early strong formulation of ecological modernization has come under a number of criticisms. The most strident is the critique that the capitalist logic of profit has not been and cannot be ecologized and any appearance as such is window-dressing (O’Connor 1994; Pellow, Schnaiber, Weinberg 2000). York and Rosa (2003) put forth a call for empirical support for the suppositions of EMT. Specifically, they seek evidence that l) the modernization of institutions yields real ecological improvements; 2) superindustrialization resulting in green production and consumption is a common occurrence; 3) overall impacts from industries and firms are being reduced and not simply shifted geographically or from one kind of impact to another; and 4) the pace of increases in resource efficiencies are outstripping the pace of increases in overall production (Clark and York 2005; York 2006). This line of criticism claims that increasing ties among business, environmental movement organizations, and the state are not a reflection of converging interests, but a tool to subordinate social movement’s goals 67 to those of business’s profit motive (Pellow et al., 2000). Buttel (2000) critiques EMT’s failure to clarify and ground itself in broader sociological theories of state-society. In response to these critiques, several tenets of the strong formulation of EMT have been weakened. The first is an acknowledgement that the pathway of development toward an ecological economy and the content of modernity is contingent upon many factors. The integration of ecological concerns is not inevitably a product of superindustrialization, but instead a product of a political process where the pathway is dependent on contestation among state, private firms and civil society groups. It is a “purposive change due to political decision making and institutional restructuring” that allows for heterogeneity in patterns of development (Perz, 2007:422). Similarly, EMT has moved away from isomorphic assumptions about the environmental outcomes of capitalism (Perz 2007). This weaker variant leaves space for contextualizing the power relationships among states, ESMOs and business, but fails to take the opportunity to specify institutional conditions, relative power relations among states, ESMOS and business, and corresponding environmental outcomes of capitalism. Contrary to EMT, TOP argues that there is a fundamental conflict between the environment and capitalist economic production. Building on the Monthly Review school Of Marxism, Schnaiberg (1980) theorizes that the institutional arrangements under monopoly capitalism result in the competition and concentration of capital that leads to increases in capital investment and technological production efficiencies. This increase in productive physical capital requires even more ecosystem resources and result in the increasing rates of withdrawals of material resources from the earth and additions of these material resources transformed into waste and deposited into the environment. This 68 cycle is referred to as the “treadmill of production.” It generally predicts a worsening Of the health of the environment through an accelerating treadmill and “environmental improvement” is understood as a substantial slowing or dismantling of the treadmill. Producers will not account for ecological harms in their decision-making unless forced to do so because it would reduce profits. The state is dependent on expanding capital production and consumption for increasing tax revenue. Workers are dependent on it for jobs. Any efforts to slow the treadmill of production are tempered by a belief by all actors that some form of economic expansion is needed to meet their material needs (Schnaiberg, 1994). In TOP, civil society and business are fighting for scarce resources and the state is a mediator that tends to favor business, but will negotiate between the two in a “managed scarcity” approach. Increasingly close relationships among these groups are generally viewed as a process of cooptation by business of group interests rather than a shared logic of ecology. TOP theory has faced its challenges over the past quarter century. Broadly, there has been a general demise in the political and academic popularity of Marxian analyses or critiques of capitalism in sociology. Hannigan (1995:22) argues that the whole model relies “exclusively on the logic of the capitalist system” and a resulting economic determinism though Buttel (1999) defends TOP against this assertion. The initial formulation of TOP was an analysis of the U.S. political economy of resource use. The majority of recent critiques are based on globalization and its impacts on the political economy theorized by TOP scholars. The expansion of neoliberal capitalism globally is theorized to have increased the power of businesses to act as they wish while diminishing the autonomy of the state to control flows of money and resources across national 69 borders. This has challenged TOP’s theorization of the nation-state as a negotiator between business and civil society’s resource needs (Sonnenfeld and M01, 2002). In addition, there is an emergence of transnational environmental movement organizations seeking to counter the rise of transnational corporate power (Gould, 2004). Treadmill theorists have accommodated these critiques in a few ways though the thrust of their argument regarding the treadmill has remained the same. One response has been to de-emphasize the role that monopoly capital plays in the model. Gould, Schnaiberg, and Pellow (2004) highlight instead how the global north’s industrial treadmill is predicated on southern natural resource pools, labor pools, markets, and waste sinks. They also focus on the increasing ease for transnational corporations to move production around globally. The authors argue that the reorganization of global capital has forced localities (nations, states, etc.) to compete with others, undermining their ability to protect the environment through political action (Gould and Schnaiberg, 1994). In addition, they recognize that the forces of the treadmill are decreasingly tied to the U.S. state (Gould, Pellow, and Schnaiberg 2004). TOP advocates argue that there are new or renewed forms of political coalitions that seek to oppose the transnational treadmill such as new environmental-labor alliances and the anticorporate globalization movement, but they maintain these coalitions are greatly diminished by local and global treadmills and commodification (Buttel 2004). A Context Dependent Theorization of Ecological Modernization and Treadmill of Production One reason the debate on TOP and EMT has lingered is that, although it is clear that each theory is not fully applicable to all cases, we may easily Observe examples of 70 each theory, particularly in recent U.S. environmental politics. A context dependent theory seeks to identify the underlying conditions for a theory’s applicability and build on it. In EMT and TOP, there are assumptions about the power relations among state, social movements and business and how each sector behaves. Rather than assume power relations are one way or another, it is better to specify the conditions under which the power relations lead to the particular theorized environmental outcomes. EMT asserts that in response to regulatory and societal pressures, businesses will internalize an ecological rationality and increase their role in ecological restructuring. The state will shift its role from command-and-control to a negotiated rulemaking agency that serves as a facilitator for bringing together businesses and civil society to realize and carry out ecological transformation. In this way, ecological modernization reflects a view of the state as described in early pluralist accounts of the state where the state is an arena where others compete to promote their subjective interests (Dahl 2005). Environmental social movement organizations (ESMOs), representing civil society interests, will increase direct negotiation with industry and the state. EMT does not have an explicit theory of power, but its focus on institutional change can be informed by recent work by new institutionalists in organizational sociology who recognize that changes in organizational fields emerge from actors that by virtue of size, legitimacy or social capital can exert power and influence change (Hoffman and Ventresca, 2002). For institutional change to occur as EMT predicts, the state and ESMOS must have enough power to influence business to adopt their ecological objectives into business’s objectives via public pressure and regulation. When recast as a context dependent theory, the relationships anticipated by EMT are likely to emerge when: 71 1) public consciousness of an issue is high increasing the societal pressures for business to adopt an ecological rationality (Cohen, 1998); 2) the state is open to public pressure to regulate industry heightening the threat of future regulation via increased political opportunity structure for the public to actualize their Obj ectives via regulation (McAdam, McCarthy, and Zald 1996x 3) the industry has already been regulated on the issue, and thus has developed ways of incorporating regulatory costs which reduces further resistance (F ineman and Clarke 1996; Parson 2003)and 4) business interests are fragmented, weakening business’s ability to oppose regulation and pursue a single interest (Mizruchi and Bey 2005). TOP theory provides a systematic view where all sectors of society have a stake in the continuance of the capitalist society that they are a part of. Thus TOP predicts a tendency to marginalize environmental factors in decision-making. TOP asserts that business does not internalize ecological rationality and maintains the core logic of profit maximization. To maximize profits firms seek to extemalize the social costs of their economic activities. Monopoly capital, the basis Of TOP’s original formulation, is characterized by a small number of capitalist corporations and low levels of competition. These factors result in a united business class that provides a strong basis for opposing regulations. Breaking with typical Marxist views of “the capitalist state” as relatively undifferentiated (Amenta, 2005), Schnaiberg (1994) describes it as differentiated agencies pursuing their own context-based goals as understood by “state-centered” theorists (Evans, Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol 1985). These goals, however, are highly 72 constrained by the imperative to support continued growth of business for jobs and maintain the tax base (O’Connor, 1973; Schnaiberg, 1980). Social movement organizations seek to reduce environmental degradation via the state, but often fail as the state chooses to protect business interests while meeting its growth imperative. TOP theory suggests that in economic crisis, the state is even more dependent on business and the influence of social movement weakens. While in times of environmental crisis, environmental social movements may increase their access to and influence in regulatory efforts. These changes last only as long the crisis lasts and then normal TOP relations return. When recast as a context dependent theory, the relationships anticipated by TOP are likely to emerge when: 1) there are high levels of business unity to oppose social movement influence on the state to force business to be responsible for environmental costs of their activities. This condition is dependent upon either a monopolistic or oligarchic industry structure with low competitive pressures and/or a strong trade industry association that facilitates industry unity (Mizruchi and Bey, 2005); 2) there is low threat of regulation and little previous regulation of an industry. This occurs particularly in times of economic crisis when state autonomy is decreased and it becomes more dependent on business decreasing receptivity to civil society concerns (Evans, Reuschemeyer, and Skocpol, 1985; Schnaiberg, 1994); 73 3) in times of resource crisis and a healthy economy and state administrations are more Open to environmental concerns. Under these conditions, states have more autonomy from business to pursue civil society’s interest in resources. This study focuses on the power relations among state, civil society and business that would lead to ecological modernization or treadmill of production processes. While the above discussion has highlighted the differences between these two theories, there are points of likeness. For example, TOP theorizes that under certain conditions the treadmill can be slowed temporarily. We may ask what is the difference between the power relations predicted for slowing the treadmill of production and ecological modernization? The key difference in original formulations of the theories is the emphasis given to the development of direct relationships between the environmental movement and business in ecological modemization. Original formulations of TOP focused on increased social movement power to influence the state (Schnaiberg. 1980). Subsequent writings on TOP suggests that if business supports a regulation or participates in a voluntary partnership, its motive is profit driven (delaying regulation could be more costly, new regulation presents additional market regulation) whereas EMT ascribes cooperation between business and ESMOS to a merging of ecological and economic rationality achieved by modernization. The “true” motives of industry are difficult to assess and are not addressed in this study. Much work has been done investigating the motivations for business action and almost all has found a range Of motives that encompass both bottom line and ethical dimensions (Bansal and Roth, 2000). The primary distinction I draw here is that EMT predicts direct cooperative interactions and 74 negotiations between ESMOS and business whereas TOP predicts that the state will mediate interactions between the two. Methods To examine dynamic organizational relations and their contexts around appliance efficiency over time I conducted archival research. The aim of my archival research was to 1) identify organizations participating in efforts to influence the definition and promotion of efficient appliances, 2) the nature of organizational relationships in these efforts, and 3) the broader social and political contexts of the relationships. To identify and describe organizational interactions around appliance efficiency fi'om 1978 to 2006, I used Department of Energy (DOE) mandatory efficiency standards rulemaking dockets, energy star negotiations, lawsuit case findings, and newspaper articles in the New York Times. Since 1978, each time the Department of Energy has sought to develop minimum energy efficiency standards it is required by law to publish in the Federal Register an advanced notice of public rulemaking that announces they are considering developing standards and identifies dates for public hearings and written comment, a notice of proposed rule that announces a proposed standard developed by the agency and identifies dates for public hearings and written comment, and a final rule that announces a final standard and addresses the comments it received in the previous commenting periods. Transcripts from these hearings and comments submitted from these rulemakings are made part of a public record. In winter 2008, I electronically searched the Federal Register (using HeinOnline) 1978 to 2006 using the key words “appliance”, “NECPA”, “NECA” or “NAECA”. This identified all federal register announcements regarding appliance energy efficiency. I then requested the dockets kept on each of the 75 events held by Department of Energy which included transcripts and attendees if it was a hearing and copies of comments received by DOE. DOE had misplaced dockets from between1980 to 1988. Negotiations from 2001-2006 on the voluntary Energy Star labeling program were retrieved from the DOE website, Environmental Protection Agency website, and in coordinationi‘with a DOE consultant who worked on the Energy Star meetings. I then conducted lawsuit case searches in relation to the policy and regulations related to appliance efficiency to identify lawsuits that had been brought. Lawsuit case background materials were useful in filling in the missing DOE data. Finally, New York Times articles were searched for any articles reporting on appliance energy efficiency and organization and events described were noted. Once these sources were compiled, the organization, individual representative, position held, date comment was made or hearing was held, and nature Of comment was then logged. Organizational characteristics such as whether it was a business, energy efficiency non-profit, trade industry, utility, state or federal governmental agency was coded. To identify the broader social and political contexts I consulted a broad range of published research on presidential administrations and energy and environmental policy (Andrews 2006; Miller 1995; Schnaiberg 1994), public opinion on environmental issues (Dunlap 1992; Dunlap and Scarce 1991), and energy efficiency advocates accounts of improving appliance efficiency (Nade12002;Nadel 1997; Rosenfeld 1999). The Shifting Political Economy of U.S. Appliance Efficiency In the early 19703, the idea of an unending supply of cheap electricity was threatened by an increasing realization of US vulnerability to foreign Oil producers and rising prices of inputs for electric and gas utilities. In addition, energy utilities were 76 encountering technological limitations Of a centralized energy system with a slowing rate of increases of efficiencies from economies of scale in electricity production. Finally, energy utilities were finding it more difficult and costly of to site new plants, including nuclear power plants (Smil 1994). These conditions led to a substantial political interest in empowering U.S. citizens to reduce their demand in energy for the first time in U.S. history. However, despite a wide understanding that energy-efficiency was an Obvious “win-win” solution with its potential to save money and save the environment (Hayes 2000), market supply and demand for energy efficiency did not materialize evenly across the economy (California Energy Commission 2005). The residential sector seemed especially laggard. Academics and advocates interested in energy efficiency sought to understand the reasons for these market failures. They identified multiple barriers to market development for energy efficient lighting and appliances including distortion of energy prices by U.S. energy policies, lack of consumer knowledge and understanding of long-term energy costs of purchases or behaviors, and split incentives where one party purchases a product and another pays the operating costs (California Energy Commission 2005). These “market barriers”, as they are referred to in the energy efficiency field, create the need for specific policies or actions to be undertaken in order to increase energy efficient product availability and demand. One of the first things state and federal policymakers did to address the market barrier of lack of consumer knowledge was to develop test procedures for appliance energy use. The intent was to provide comparable measures of appliance energy use consumers so consumers could compare and choose. The development of these test procedures also provided a basis for defining efficient appliances through voluntary 77 labeling programs or eliminating the worst energy performing products through minimtun efficiency standards. From the early 1970s, policymakers discussed both voluntary and mandatory approaches discussed for defining and promoting efficient products in the marketplace. States like California and New York led, while the federal government followed. Defining a product as energy efficient or not efficient is a political process that leads to an environmental outcome. It is political because the decision is one where various parties have a stake in the outcome and power relations are enacted to decide “who gets what, when and how”(Laswell 1936). Higher levels of efficiency for an appliance mean, all things being held constant, avoided need for energy supplies and reductions in greenhouse gas emissions and air pollutants from the avoidance of fossil fuels extraction and combustion. The development of appliance efficiency specifications has been a rocky road characterized by antagonistic relationships, lawsuits, cooperative coalitions, broken coalitions, and administrative interventions. The U.S. national laboratories provide exhaustive analyses of the economic and technological Options and impacts for mandatory rulemakings of efficiency standards. Efficiency advocates and manufacturers closely scrutinize the assumptions and meaning of what is technologically and economically feasible inevitably comes under close scrutiny (American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy, 1996; Association for Home Appliance Manufacturers, 1996). All sides lay claim to being experts and the national lab scientists must defend their objectivity and findings against claims of “ineptitude and bias” (Association for Home Appliance Manufacturers, 1996). Manufacturers of the products being defined have an interest in ensuring that they are already producing items meeting the efficiency 78 standard or that they can produce these products without high incremental investments. Depending on these relative competitive advantages that manufacturers have they may vary in support for level of efficiency being specified in a standard. Often manufacturers producing products with the highest levels of efficiency are most opposed to an increase in mandatory minimum standards as it raises the floor making it harder to differentiate their product from others. Energy efficiency, consumer, and environmental advocates have sought to set levels of efficiency higher ensuring maximum savings for consumers and reductions of impacts on the environment. Meanwhile the state’s position in these debates has varied from objective negotiator to interested party with agencies facing off and all three branches of government intervening at various points. In this study, I utilize archival materials from debates defining energy efficiency as well as data on sociopolitical conditions to explore how changes in sociopolitical and economic conditions are correlated with changing power relations among state, environmental social movement, and business relations. Each sector theorized is conceptualized as a population of organizations. Though TOP and EMT theorize capitalist political economy and the environment in terms of the state, business, and social movements at the societal sector, recognizing that the logics of these relations are carried out by organizations embedded within that institution enables us to carry out a grounded analysis of the power relations among organizations. This approach also recognizes that actors embedded in these institutions have varying levels of agency in how they interpret and apply these logics (Burns and Dietz 1992; Clemens and Cook 1999). This approach has been utilized extensively in political sociology (Clemens 1997; Hooks 1993; Laumann, Knoke, and Kim 1985). 79 In this study, the state is instantiated as government agencies, business as for- profit organizations and industry associations, and social movements as non-profit organizations advocating for energy efficiency. The extent to which the non-profit organizations involved “energy efficiency” debates are environmental social movement organizations is arguable. There is-certainly some overlap with the mainstream environmental movement. Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC) is highly active in the energy efficiency field with Sierra Club and others occasionally participating I (particularly in partnership with NRDC). In addition, there are many more locally based organizations that have their roots in the early “appropriate technology movement” of the early 1970’s such as the Center for Neighborhood Technology of Chicago and Center for Energy and Environment in Minneapolis. However, many organizations involved are dedicated specifically to energy efficiency at the national or regional level (i.e. the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy or the Northwest Energy Efficiency Alliance). These organizations, though talking about the environmental benefits of energy efficiency, have no public membership, and employ a highly professional staff with a focus on technical expertise. The process of defining energy efficient residential appliances is a useful empirical case for this purpose for three reasons. First, efforts to improve energy efficiency have drawn attention from both EMT and TOP advocates (Schnaiberg, 1994; Mo] and Spargaaren, 2004). Schnaiberg (1994) suggests that the politics of energy efficiency that have emerged is an example of the state and business’s dedication to upholding the capitalist treadmill. In his case study on the political economy of energy policymaking he reminds us that two options emerged in response to the rising oil prices. 80 The appropriate technology movement sought to “dismantle the treadmill and substitute a more subsistence-like, stable, intermediate technology” (Schnaiber,l994:27; Schumacher 1973). Meanwhile, Amory Lovins put forth the less radical “soft energy pa ” that focused on energy efficiency (Lovins and Thorndike 1978). Schnaiberg has characterized the focus on energy efficiency that has prevailed as a “change in the forces of production associated with energy transformations with little change in business-labor class relations” as opposed to the appropriate technology movement which sought to alter production and class relations (Schnaiberg, 1994: 28). He argues that in this way the treadmill of production and its relations were preserved by energy efficiency. Meanwhile, advances in energy efficiency through cooperative market-based approaches used to promote it have served as a prime example of ecological modernization (Melchert 2007). The second reason I focus on the case of residential energy efficiency is that past studies indicates that power relations among the sectors have influenced the development and adoption of energy efficiency policies and multiple approaches to efficiency have evolved over time (Varone and Aebischer 2001). Finally, the availability of historical notices, transcripts from meetings, and organizational comments in negotiations available from proceedings on mandatory and voluntary negotiations on appliance efficiency allow for a detailed analysis of organizational participation and stances on these issues. The Face of Treadmill of Production 1981-1986: Reaganism, Pre-Regulation, and Resistance In 1977, the energy crisis was back on the pages of the newspapers and in people’s minds with 301 articles being run in the New York Times. During the 1973-74 OPEC embargo the New York Times had run 929 articles with “energy crisis” or a 81 related term in its headlines or first paragraph, but this had fallen to a mere 31 articles in 1976. The general public’s support for government doing more to protect the environment had fallen from its highs in the early 19708 but hovered around 50% (Dunlap 1992; Dunlap and Scarce 1991). Subsequent to the first wave of the energy crisis, the Republican Ford administration had taken a voluntary approach issuing a federal directive that suggested the energy efficiency of residential appliances attain voluntary 20% improvement targets (subsequently formalized in the Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975). In 1977, the Democratic Carter Administration came into power and proposed mandatory energy efficiency standards for residential products. The debate over making energy efficiency standards mandatory was contentious in the U.S. Congress, generally falling along party lines. In the end, the National Energy Conservation and Policy Act (ECPA) of 1978 was adopted with mandatory energy efficiency standards. The Department Of Energy (DOE), under the Carter administration, formulated minimum energy efficiency standards and was near implementing them when a change of presidential party occurred once again (Nadel 1997) In 1981, Ronald Reagan took over the White House and a new Republican Administration began. Reagan called for the abolition of the DOE and saw little need for an energy policy beyond the strategic petroleum reserve and a strong military presence in the Middle East. His budget director, David Stockman, expressed the Reagan philosophy as "strategic reserves and strategic forces" (Miller, 1995: 2). Consistent with the anti- govemment intervention, free market philosophy of the administration, a notice of intent was promptly published in the Federal Register on February 23rd to review the standards 82 developed by DOE under the Carter Administration for nine appliances. The notice of intent noted the administration’s particular concerns about the “economic justification” for the energy efficiency standards (CAS-RM-78-100 Comment 8). The Reagan administration’s review of the standards and general anti-regulatory stance signaled to industry a decreased probability that national appliance standards would be enacted. In addition, the public’s concern for environmental and energy issues diminished as support for environmental regulation dropped to new lows and the 1979 energy crisis disappeared from the newspaper pages with falling oil prices. Meanwhile, the economy remained a focus of attention as the U.S. economy plunged into a deep recession in 1981. Under these conditions we expect the power relations predicted by TOP to emerge where 1) the state, with decreasing autonomy due to economic crisis, favors business interests’ 2) civil society has little opportunity to influence the state to protect the environment and 3) competing business and civil society interests are mediated by the state. Inspecting newspaper articles from the New York Times and transcripts from the regulatory hearings (Docket CAS RM-79-113, Comment #3) there is no evidence of cooperative relationships between business and non-govemmental organizations. The state’s interest in not regulating the market, including energy efficiency, is aligned with appliance manufacturers’ interests in not being regulated. In October of 1981, left with no other opportunity to influence the state’s adoption of mandatory standards, the Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC) and Consumers Union of the United States filed suit against DOE to compel promulgation of appliance efficiency standards (NRDC, Inc. v. Edwards, Civ. No. 8102546). On April 2, 1982, DOE published its findings on its review of the Carter administration’s proposed 83 standards. DOE found that the previously proposed standards neither provided significant energy savings, nor were economically justified as required by Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975. DOE’s findings were based on drastic revisions of what "significant" savings meant and re-calculations of the benefits and burdens of mandatory standards. Based on these findings, DOE proposed that no standards were justifiable for any of the eight appliances that were to be covered under EPCA (47 Fed.Reg. 14,424: 1982). This came to be referred to by the energy efficiency advocacy community as the “no standards standard.” As required by procedural law, DOE provided opportunity for comment on the proposed rule. DOE'S notice did not state when DOE would make its final decision on appliance efficiency so NRDC and Consumers Union pressed forward with their litigation to force DOE to implement standards. DOE settled the suit by agreeing to establish efficiency standards no later than October 29, 1982, unless prevented by good cause (47 F ed.Reg. 57,198, 57,200: 1982). DOE failed to meet that deadline. On December 22, 1982, DOE published its final rule determining that standards for kitchen ranges and ovens and for clothes dryers would not result in significant conservation of energy and in any event would not be economically justified. On August 30th, 1983, DOE announced its refusal to prescribe mandatory standards for the six remaining priority products (48 Fed.Reg. 39,376: 1983). DOE concluded that for seven of the eight appliances considered in the December 1982 and August 1983 rules, standards would not result in significant conservation and would not be economically justified. For the eighth, central air conditioners, DOE concluded that a standard would result in significant conservation but would not be economically justified. These final rules ended federal consideration Of 84 standards for the eight appliances and pre-empted state efficiency regulation of those appliances. DOE also decided that it was not required to prepare an environmental assessment or environmental impact statement for its "no-standard standard" determinations. These decisions by DOE illustrate it pursuing the objectives that met its immediate needs for administration approval and business profit in the face of economic crisis. Its manipulation of the tests that determined the significance of savings and costs of energy efficiency clearly aligns its interests with the interests of targeted regulated manufacturers at the expense of public and environmental interests in energy conservation. In its determination of “no-standard standards” the Republican executive branch clearly favored appliance industry interests which focused on avoiding the costs entailed in re-tooling manufacturing plants for energy efficiency. The Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC), Consumers Union of the United States, Representative Richard Ottinger (Democrat from New York), the California State Energy Resources Conservation and Development Commission, the State of Minnesota, and the State of New York filed suit against the Department of Energy once again (NRDC v. Herrington, 768 F.2d 1355). The State of Texas Energy Office, the Northwest Power Planning Council, the Florida Department of Community Affairs (Energy Office), the Oregon Department of Energy, and the Iowa Commerce Commission provided support for the petitioners’ claims. Various appliance manufacturers and the Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers intervened in support of the Secretary of Energy Herrington. The court’s findings from this lawsuit are instructive on how definitions can be influenced by powerful organizations to fit their agenda in appliance standards. DOE had 85 redefined what was technologically feasible to only those products currently available on the U.S. market and would not consider any prototype technologies or technologies currently available in foreign markets. Economic justifiability was limited to a 5 year pay back from a technology’s specific energy savings even though all appliances under consideration last between 12-23 years. The discount rate for consumer decisions was doubled from 5% to 10%. The lack of Opportunity for efficiency advocates to influence DOE is exemplified in the court’s findings that DOE had violated section 336(a)(2) of EPCA. That section provides that in prescribing energy efficiency standard “the Secretary shall, by means of conferences or other informal procedures, afford any interested party an opportunity to question employees of the United States who have made written or oral presentations, with respect to disputed issues of material fact. Such Opportunity shall be afforded to the extent the Secretary determines that the questioning pursuant to such procedures is likely to result in a more timely and effective resolution of such issues.” In a 1982 hearing, NRDC had requested to ask questions in person and they were denied but told to submit questions in writing. NRDC submitted six questions regarding the appliance rulemaking and DOE replied that the questions failed to demonstrate how their questioning would result in a more timely and effective resolution. DOE wrote back to NRDC that NRDC needed to identify the disputed issues of fact and who they wanted to question for DOE to reconsider. However, when NRDC submitted these materials they were again denied the Opportunity to question DOE (Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. v. Herrington, 768 F.2d 1355 DC. Cir. 1985). 86 The “no standards” standards were set aside by the courts in the NRDC v. Herrington and rulemaking for standards ordered to start again. This ruling, along with the state-level energy standards already in place, made national mandatory appliance efficiency standards more likely. The major appliance manufacturer organizations began negotiations in ear1y1986 with the Natural Resources Defense Council to develop national standards. An agreement was reached in July 1986, which was subsequently written as proposed legislation based on previously enacted state standards. This legislation was introduced in August 1986 in both Houses of Congress (HR. 5465, S. 2781). The legislation was largely viewed by manufacturers and states as a compromise — states gave up the right to develop their own standards providing manufacturers the “non-patchwork” unified national market they needed and in return manufacturers acquiesced to national standards to be updated periodically. On November 1, 1986, despite industry support for it, President Reagan pocket vetoed the measure. He argued that appliance efficiency standards were not consonant with the administration’s policy of minimal Federal regulatory involvement in the marketplace. The next year, however, Congress passed an essentially identical bill (S. 83, or the National Appliance Energy Conservation Act referred to as NAECA) on March 3, and President Reagan signed it on March 17,1987, ending the 9 year struggle to implement the first mandatory appliance energy efficiency standards. In the years of 1980 to 1986, I find that the case of appliance energy efficiency supports my context dependent theory of TOP and the expected political outcomes. The Reagan administration’s laissezfaire market approach along with the 1981-1982 recession that assured state dependence on business resulted in the threat of regulation 87 being low. As a result, business was not inclined to cooperate with environmental groups and energy advocates to pursue efficiency goals. The lack of political opportunity to influence the state lead to the kinds of oppositional politics described by TOP where regional and state energy offices with energy efficiency advocates pursued their interests through the courts to enforce the statutory laws and required DOE to carry out its regulatory functions. In the end, the courts upheld their role as an independent adjudicator of the law. This highlights the important role the judicial branch has played in enabling environmental policies, once in place, to have real impact despite shifts in political administration and public opinion. Although lawsuits are decried as expensive, time-consuming, and blamed for negative and combative relations among the societal sectors, they have often provided ESMO’s with their only opportunity to pursue their interests when the state and business interests are dominant. With the court’s ruling, national mandatory standards become imminent. This increased threat of regulation, along with the growing state patchwork of appliance standards, provided the conditions where business capitulated and agreed to negotiate with efficiency advocates. The Face of Ecological Modernization 1992-2001: Pre-negotiated Standards and Market Transformation Once the first mandatory standards were implemented, a transition of power relations occurs among ESMOS, government and industry. After a low of 49.7% in 1980, public support for environmental regulation resurged in 1990 to 69.8% of the general public supporting increased government involvement to protect the environment (Dunlap, 1992; Dunlap and Scarce, 1991). While the first Bush administration was a continuation Of the Republican policies of Reagan, it was arguably not as ardent in its dedication to the 88 free market. The Bush administration also faced the reality of foreign Oil disruptions once again with the first Iraq War (Miller, 1995). Recognizing the problem of a patchwork of state standards, the Bush administration did not block new national standards that had industry support. In 1988 and 1991, motivated by states establishing standards for products not covered by NAECA, manufacturers and efficiency advocates negotiated new standards for ultimately these discussions led to passage of federal legislation in 1988 establishing efficiency standards for fluorescent lamp ballasts. In 1992, the Energy Policy Act expanded standards to include a variety of lamps, electric motors, and commercial heating, cooling, and plumbing products. By 1992, the Association for Home Appliance Manufacturers (AHAM) and its manufacturers were negotiating standards with Natural Resources Defense Council, the American Council for an Energy-Efficient Economy (ACEEE) and a number of states (most prominently California, Massachusetts and New York) to bring to DOE on a regular basis. In 1993, the Democratic Clinton administration entered the White House after 12 years of Republican rule. While the Democrats willingness to regulate industry was higher than that of the previous Republican administration, the Clinton Administration had also adopted rhetoric consistent with the ideas of ecological modernization espousing a willingness to provide more innovative approaches and work more cooperatively. Miller’s (1995) analysis Of the early energy policy under the Clinton administration documents a switch to market-based approaches as a substitute for more prescriptive regulatory mandates. Miller points to: 1)the Clinton administration’s support of "market transforming" strategies emphasized in Climate Change Action Plan, 2)the system of competitive bidding for new power plants that has evolved in response to Public Utility 89 Regulatory Policies Act, 3) the emissions trading system central to the acid rain program for coal burning power plants incorporated in the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990, and 4) the concept of "joint implementation," a variant of emissions trading included in the F rarnework Convention on Climate Change. All of these programs provided regulated industry with greater latitude in choosing the means to achieve energy and environmental goals, while creating incentives for technological innovation. This reflects a changing role of the state around energy issues as it moved to become a “market facilitator.” In the meantime, environmental and energy groups identified and built new relationships with an unexpected “big business” — electric power utilities. Utilities are in the business Of selling energy — so why the interest in efficiency? Some electric utility companies facing strict regulations and public opposition to the building of new power plants and/or transmission infrastructure still needed to meet the increasing energy demands of industry and the public. Often these utilities have challenges meeting the highest times Of public electricity use (called peak demand), which occur on the hottest days when customers all run air-conditioners at the same time. Utilities serving the metropolitan areas of California and the densely populated northeast corridor from Boston to New York City are the most affected by the problem of peak demand. Reduction in appliance energy use was a relatively inexpensive way to avoid expensive power plant construction for utilities. State regulators had been supporting this approach by using efficiency as part of the least cost planning process for utilities. In fact, many states collected a small surcharge on energy use called a systems benefit charge that was dedicated to run energy efficiency programs to decrease demands. Mandatory energy 90 efficiency standards are essentially a way for electric utilities to shift costs from their industry to the appliance industry. Recognizing these overlapping interests in energy efficiency, lead to innovations in industry and environmental movement partnerships that are characteristic of ecological modernization in the appliance efficiency field. For example, the 1993 Clinton/Gore U.S. Climate Change Action Plan cites the 1990 Super Efficient Refrigerator Program (SERP) as an example of a favored approach that emphasizes ESMO-industry cooperative efforts that have a minimal role for government (Gore 1993). The idea of SERP was born in 1990 during discussions between Pacific Gas & Electric (PG&E), the nation’s largest investor-owned utility, and NRDC on how utilities could best leverage their money to gain the most energy saving. PG&E, ACEEE, and NRDCE proceeded to organize SERP with twenty-four utilities from a range of states to pool $30 million to award the manufacturer that could build the most efficient CF C-free refrigerator at the lowest cost. The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) provided a minimal amount of money and had limited involvement. SERP went on to be incorporated as the Consortium for Energy Efficiency which develops voluntary specification for appliances for utilities running conservation programs. Indeed these kinds of approaches became encompassed in an approach commonly referred to as “market transformation.” Market transformation is a “process whereby energy-efficiency innovations are introduced into the marketplace and over time penetrate a large portion of the eligible market.” (Geller and Nadel 1994). The strategies are targeted at increasing technology diffusion and include research and development, demonstration and field tests, commercialization incentives, marketing and consumer 91 education, grants, loans, and tax incentives, voluntary commitments, bulk purchases, building codes and appliance standards (Geller and Nadel, 1994). In 1997, the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy instituted an annual “Market Transformation” Symposium in Washington, DC. This is an example of an evolution of partnerships between utilities and other industries on the one hand and environmentalists on the other that allow for mutually beneficial outcomes, as opposed to litigation and regulatory confrontations that produce winners and losers. However, these approaches only work with the Options to litigate and regulate still in play to encourage compromise and the search for common ground. An instructive example of this occurred in 1994 when there was a change in control Of Congress and Newt Gingrich led renewed efforts to dismantle DOE and reduce regulation. In the 90’s efforts were underway to revise the first set of standards put into place in 1986. The revision of mandatory standards by DOE involves conducting analyses, proposing standard levels, soliciting public comments, and then issuing final standards. While this type of process sometimes works successfully, this process has often lead to bitter fights among competing interests and resulted in a standard that several parties were dissatisfied with. An alternative to this type Of formal standard-setting process is for manufacturers, consumers, ESMOS, and government agencies to work together to negotiate on standard levels. This has often been done with limited government involvement where parties then bring the “pre-negotiated” standard to DOE to adopt. On November 11, 1994, the Natural Resources Defense Council, Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers and American Council for an Energy Efficient 92 Economy, along with the New York State Energy Office, the California Energy Commission, Pacific Gas & Electric, and Southern California Edison, presented joint comments to the U.S. Department of Energy describing a two-year negotiation process and a pre-negotiated standard for refrigerators, refrigerator-freezers, and freezers. All parties above expressed that rulemaking procedures, even informal rulemakings such as those conducted under NAECA, tend to cause participants to take relatively rigid, adversarial, and ideological positions. The manufacturers, advocates, and utilities that had participated in the negotiation process expressed hope that the informal pre- negotiations would facilitate the candid sharing of information and development of more innovative approaches. For manufacturers, the pre-negotiation of standards provided certainty about the products they would need to produce in the future. Negotiating the standards before the formal DOE rulemaking also provided manufacturers extra lead time to re-tool for the new standards and to coordinate this re-tooling with CFC phase-outs. Non-industry participants were motivated to participate by improved access to manufacturer’s technical and economic information. This enabled them to make more informed judgments as to the economic feasibility of different levels of energy efficiency along avoiding the costs of participating in prolonged rulemakings. All parties to the negotiations urged the DOE to act quickly to enable manufacturers to prepare for the upcoming implementation. However, the Republicans had captured Congress. In 1995, allegedly at the prompting of AHAM (National Association of State Energy Offices, 1995), a proposal for a moratorium on new appliance efficiency standards was inserted into the Interior and Related Agencies Appropriations Act for Fiscal 1996. On July 20‘“, 1995 DOE published the Notice of 93 Proposed Rule that, for the most part, adopted the jointly proposed pre-negotiated standards as its proposed levels. In a letter dated August 11, 1995, AHAM requested a postponement of the hearings and written comment deadline because of the legislative proposals before Congress to withhold appropriations for DOE appliance standards making, which would delay the adoption of the standards. In a hearing on October 25, 1995, AHAM made oral comments backing away from the pre-negotiated standards by taking a “no standing” on the proposed rule as the legislation had been passed by the U.S. House Of Representatives and Senate. Whirlpool, an AHAM member, broke with the trade industry by voicing disapproval of AHAM’s silence on the issue and continued support for the joint proposal and DOE’s proposed rule. Whirlpool acknowledged it had a good competitive position in relation to the standard with plenty of products that met the standard on the market, but also cited that it felt it had an “ethical obligation” to stand by the standards it had agreed to (Whirlpool, 1995). ACEEE and NRDC also continued their support with the proviso that if DOE re-opened the rulemaking the compromises they agreed to in the pre-negotiation phase would have to be revisited. On August 12, 1996 the U.S. Doe published a second Notice of Proposed Rule that re-opened negotiations for new refrigerator/freezer standards. In the end, the pro-negotiated standards that had been negotiated since 1992 became effective in 2001. Discussion and Conclusion This study illustrates that recognizing the broader sociopolitical conditions that alter societal power relations provides insight into when TOP or EMT theories are applicable. By using this context-sensitive approach, it is clear that TOP theory is instructive in explaining power relations among state, business and civil society during 94 the early Reagan years of first trying to regulate energy efficiency in residential appliances. However, EMT proved similarly useful for explaining more cooperative direct business-ESMO efforts to improve energy efficiency of appliances during the Clinton presidency. In contrast to the Reagan years where the state strongly favored business interests, during the Clinton years there was a purposefirl effort by business to directly engage with local and state government and environmental movement organizations with limited federal involvement. In addition, the Clinton government developed as a market facilitator, rather than command-and-control regulator, through such programs as the voluntary labeling programs meant to foster less mandatory regulation and more cooperative efforts to bring efficient appliances to market in adherence with EMT. This study highlights the sensitivity of these two theories to the strength Of the state and unity of the capitalist class and the state’s likelihood to pass regulations on behalf of public interests that are at odds with business interests. There are a couple of characteristics that make the case of appliance energy efficiency unique and may limit its generalizability in studying power relations of TOP and EMT. Appliance efficiency standards deal with the product made by industry rather than the process of production (though the design of the product can be considered part of the production process). Thus the targeted change is to get manufacturers to produce an energy efficient product for consumers, not to make their production practices more efficient, which is the primary focus of theories of ecological modernization of production and treadmill of production. There is some evidence that corporations approach these two types of decisions separately, weighing different factors. A good example can be found in the automobile industry. Ford Motor Company arguably has 95 greater resource production efficiencies than other manufacturers, but the automobile fleet it produces has lower average miles per gallon than other car manufacturers (Levy and Rothenberg, 2002). These differences are likely due to differences in corporate assessment of profit potentials. Ford perceives an opportunity to make profit by reducing resource input expenses while perceiving that there is not a profit opportunity in producing more fuel efficient cars. Both TOP and EMT focus on production processes not on consumption efficiency. The theories are calibrated at the level of states and industries, while the case study is more micro in focus. Since TOP theorizes that changes in the production process that conserve resources take the profits from the increased efficiencies and make additional investments in business that speeds up withdrawals from the environment, it does not predict the environmental impacts of decisions about what products to produce. This leads us to the second unique characteristic of the case of residential energy efficient appliances, which is that it is a case where the economic signals are muted thus significantly reducing the market mechanism that is at the heart of EMT. EMT argues that rising prices for resources that come about through the internalization of environmental costs will lead to increased efficiencies of resource use in the production process. In this case, residential consumers have electricity prices that are kept relatively low via regulation, dampening the consumer demand for energy efficient products. In addition, for renters, there is a split incentive because building owners pay the first costs of the appliances, but the renter will pay the electricity bill. Because of this, historically manufacturers do not perceive a profitable consumer market for energy efficient products. This has begun to change and show greater amounts of variation, particularly 96 as energy-efficient products have come under the broader heading of popular “green” products. However, in this case, there is a failure to internalize the ecological externalities in the production of electricity. This trickles down to the production of energy using products (Norberg-Bohm 2000). The uniqueness of this case indicates that the contexts of business-state-civil society power relations could be further contextualized toward a theory of “green” consumer products. There has been a great deal written about the power of markets to bring about changes in the environmental impacts and human safety of products, but the political economy of consumer products and market failures must be understood. In effect, the contextualized theories of EMT and TOP power relations offered could apply to any case where there is a conflict between multiple users’ interests and producer’s interests in a product. If market signals are clear and the economic is ecologized and the ecology is economized, then production processes will automatically become more resource efficient and end-users will demand more efficient, green, safe products (Mol, 1995; Spaargaren, 1997; Mo] and Spaargaren, 2000) and we are left with only assessing whether the outcome is an environmentally significant improvement (EMT) or environmentally insignificant improvement (TOP). However, market failures are commonplace in environmental problems and the context dependent theory I propose is focused on the predicted power relations in EMT and TOP that determine what ecology gets economized and what economy gets ecologized and how that happens. That is — what is internalized and extemalized is a result of the exercise of power. In addition to the theoretical insights this research has some important implications for U.S. policy efforts to address climate change. Currently greenhouse gas 97 producing fossil fuels - coal, oil and natural gas — provide more than 85% of all energy consumed in the United States (U .S. Department of Energy, 2008). Reducing the United States’ use of these fuels is one of the major pathways to mitigating its contributions to climate change. Since this study is focused on the political economy of a consumer product, it makes a contribution to understanding the political economic context of consumer choices to reduce their energy consumption and Carbon footprint. Although there is a strong body of social science research on energy consumption and behavior (Stern and Gardener, 2008), this study aligns with one aspect of the treadmill model in that it focuses more on economic structure and political power as the context for consumer decisions (Gould, Pellow, and Schnaiberg, 2004). That is, while much of the research focuses on why consumers choose an efficient or inefficient appliance, this research highlights the political and economic reasons for why they have the choices they have. The widespread availability of affordable energy efficient products is an essential condition of empowering U.S. citizens to reduce their climate change impact. If Reagan had not been elected, it is arguable that the standards developed under the Carter administration would have been implemented and consmners would have been making choices across a very different range of efficient appliances in 1983 than the ones they had to choose from under Reagan. This study also informs us about some of the challenges for policies intended to make energy efficient products more available. Energy efficiency is often pointed to as the most economically feasible way to reduce energy demand — the “low hanging fruit” in addressing climate change (Pacala and Socolow, 2004; Hays, 2000). Yet, a review of energy efficiency history in the U.S. reveals that the path to improving efficiency has not 98 been particularly straightforward or smooth. Even when there are technologies on the shelf for making energy using products more efficient, both regulatory and non- regulatory approaches require a strong commitment of resources from the state, ESMOS and industry. All policies to reform the U.S.’s contribution to climate change are challenging, but the perception that improving technological energy-efficiency is an easily negotiated “win-win” policy is misleading if history predicts the future. The second insight this study provides is on the significant role of regulation in the development of efforts characterized by ecological modernization. While many nations have moved ahead with binding greenhouse gas reduction goals, the U.S. climate change policy has consistently rejected any mandatory climate change policies. It instead has focused on the voluntary market approaches described in ecological modernization. Some in industry, facing climate change regulations at the state level (a lawsuit currently underway between California and the Environmental Protection Agency) and international level, have surmised regulation is imminent and have taken a proactive stance of requesting the U.S. adopt a climate regulatory regime. However, the Bush Global Climate Change Policy Book of 2002, after setting voluntary emission reduction levels, states “If, in 2012, we find that we are not on track toward meeting our goal, and sound science justifies further policy action, the United States will respond with additional measures that may include a broad, market-based program as well as additional incentives and voluntary measures designed to accelerate technology development and deployment”(National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration 2002). An understanding of the conditions that encourage dedication of resources by industry towards an issue in cooperation with ESMOS and the state suggests that a purely 99 voluntary approach without regulation or the threat Of regulation is unlikely to lead to action on climate change. 100 CHAPTER THREE Friend or Foe? Energy Efficiency Advocacy Organizations’ Embeddedness and Decisions to Partner with Business Introduction The tactics environmental social movement organizations use to pursue the protection of environmental resources in the interest of the public is theorized to be an important determinant of ecological integrity (Brulle, 2000; Schnaiberg, 1980). Theories of environmental degradation and improvement in environmental sociology all provide an important role for environmental social movement organizations (referred to as environmental organizations from here on). Treadmill of production theory proposes that a strong environmental movement provides the major counter-force to business’s expanding demand for resources by pressuring the state to regulate industry’s use of resources and disposal of waste (Schnaiberg, 1980; Gould and Schnaiberg, 1994). In ecological modernization theory, environmental organizations are theorized to play an important role in cooperatively engaging directly with businesses to pursue environmental solutions through negotiated regulations and market-based approaches (Mol, 1995). In the U.S., many environmental organizations have undertaken these cooperative approaches with industry, many have continued to pursue industry change through governmental regulation and enforcement, and many have done both. Changes in the state’s willingness to adopt regulatory approaches, the nature of environmental problems, increased politicization of consumerism, and the structure of industry have all been theorized to explain the evolution of market approaches to addressing 101 environmental problems (Cohen 2006; Jaffee 2007; Konefal 2007; Pellow 2001). In this paper, I explore the organizational level factors that explain differences between environmental organization’s tactical decisions in who to engage with in pursuing their environmental goals. To explore this question, I utilize the case of U.S. energy, consumer, and environmental advocacy organizations (EEAOs) that seek to influence the energy efficiency of appliances and their decisions to partner with business to pursue these goals. Residential energy use has negative impacts on the environment because the production of electricity requires the extraction and combustion of fossil fuels, such as petroleum and coal, and these processes contribute significantly to water pollution, air pollution, and climate change. Since the 19705, there has been a concerted effort by energy efficiency advocacy organizations (EEAOs) to improve the efficiency of home appliances. Organizations advocating for energy efficiency have included environmental organizations, along with advocates for consumer rights, low-income residential energy users, and energy conservation. EEAOs’ efforts to improve appliance efficiency have focused on: 1) regulatory approaches by lobbying the state for mandatory standards 2) consumer-based approaches through voluntary product labeling and consumer education efforts and 3) market-based approaches to work with businesses and consumers to create supply and demand for efficient appliances. EEAOs must make assessments of tactics for pursuing their goals. They must consider how cooperating with and/or fighting against businesses may increase or decrease their effectiveness in reaching their goals. They may perceive the decision to work with business in a way consistent with treadmill Of production theorists - fraught 102 with risks to organizational independence. Or they may view it in a way consistent with ecological modernization theorists — an opportunity to pursue mutually beneficial objectives. In this study, I seek to shed some light on the organizational dynamics of institutional change by understanding how an EEAO’s immediate social environment and interactions influences subsequent decisions regarding these tactical decisions about partnering. To do this, I first develop a theoretical understanding of Situated strategic organizational action that builds on integrative theories of political and organizational institutional theory. I then conduct a longitudinal network analysis Of ESMO participation in face-to-face appliance energy efficiency events from 2001-2006. Using a clustering algorithm, I identify cohesive subgroups of organizations and events that constitute an organization’s immediate environment. Logistic regression analysis is used to analyze the relationship between the organization’s immediate organizational environment and subsequent EEAO decisions of whether to co-author a paper with a business organization. An EEAO’s decision to co-author a paper with a business is considered significant for several reasons. EEAO’s are not like academic organizations where submitting papers for conferences is an automatic expectation and co-authorship between academics is relatively free of organizational affiliations. Instead, the decision to cO-author a paper is a dedication of staff resources and time to writing a paper that the EEAO will not have sole decision-making authority on its content. In addition, the co- authorship of a paper between an EEAO and a business is a public declaration of historical record Of a working partnership between the two organizations. In addition, while the co-authorship of a paper is not always indicative of a deeper relationship, many 103 co-authored papers written for the conference report on “lessons learned” from on-going joint efforts to improve energy efficiency. Theoretical Approach Since the late 1970’s, organizational sociology has paid an increasing amount of attention to the impact of interorganizational relations on organizational actions. In particular, new institutional theory has had increasing power in explaining the social organization of life over the past three decades (Scott and Davis, 2007). New institutionalism has been an especially popular theoretical frame for studying natural environment issues because of the importance of institutional forces on organizational environmental decision-making (Bansal and Gao, 2006:463; Ventresca and Hoffman, 2005). In addition, there have been many synergies identified between new institutional theory and social movement theory seeking to understand the organizational basis of movement strength, ideology and tactics (Davis and McAdam, 2005; Campbell, 2005). New institutional theory focuses on how the organizational field an organization is embedded within influences organizational form and actions. Scott (1995:56) describes an organizational field as “a community of organizations that partakes Of a common meaning system and whose participants interact more frequently and fatefully with one another than with actors outside the field.” Organizational fields have commonly been understood and studied as interorganizational networks (Powell and DiMaggio 1991; Powell, White, Koput, and Owen-Smith 2005). Hoffman (1999:351) argues that fields are actually formed “around issues that bring together various field constituents with disparate purposes.” While initial work on organizational fields in new institutionalism focused on the homogenizing effects of fields (DiMaggio and Powell, 104 1983), much subsequent work has focused on how organizational fields can lead to diverse organizational responses and change (Baum and Oliver 1991; Brint and Karabel 1991; Fligstein 1991; Greenwood and Hinings 1996). In this paper, I utilize work from those who have theorized diversity and change in organizations by combining new institutional theory’s emphasis on the importance of cultural scripts and logics of the organizational environment with “old” institutionalisms’s emphasis on agentic political action (Greenwood and Hinings, 1996; Clemens, 1997). The social world consists of multiple heterogeneous institutions and each institution has its own rules or logics that guide what is appropriate behavior (Clemens, 1997). An organization and its members all come to an organizational field with past social experiences and these “logics of appropriateness” compete for meaning and legitimacy in an organizational field. An organization’s specific social location within the field makes certain logics more appropriate or likely to be enacted than others (Dacin, Goodstein, and Scott 2002). An organization’s social location is determined by its interactions with other organizations and the context of these interactions. An EEAO’s decision to pursue a cooperative action with a business means that an organization has determined that the action is an appropriate way to pursue its goals. An organization that abstains from cooperative behavior or pursues other tactics, such as bringing a lawsuit, is guided by alternative logics. The uneven adoption of various logics results in change and heterogeneity in an organizational field. There are two important aspects to this theoretical perspective that I advance through my study: 1) relations are uneven within organizational fields resulting in uneven adoption of competing logics and 2) these logics guide subsequent actions that 105 reconfigures the organizational field. To account for the uneven adoption of logics, we must understand that there is an unequal distribution of power and influence (Brint and Karabel, 1991). Scott’s (1995:56) delineation of an organizational field as those who interact “more frequently and fatefully with one another than those outside the field” is usefirl. However, it is important to recognize that there are variations in the frequency and significance of interactions between organizations within a field. Organizations not only interact to different extents (frequency), but the organizations involved and kind of resources (money, information) that are exchanged in those interactions influences how significant they are. A powerful organization, by nature of its size, legitimacy or social capital, may have disproportionate influence on what comes to be seen as the appropriate organizational form or action to take in a field. The recognition of varying abilities of organizations to influence an organizational field must be complemented by the recognition of varying agentic potential of organizations to resist influence and adopt alternative logics. Organizations can undertake a constrained range of strategic actions, such as the formation of organizational alliances that can lead to changes in organizational relations and field configuration. The reconfiguration of the organizational field results in the alteration of corresponding institutions through political negotiations that reflect the interests of the newly formed field (Oliver, 1991). In this paper I utilize Hoffman’s (1999:351) definition of an organizational field being organized around an issue, the definition and promotion of appliance energy efficiency, to analyze organizational relations among business, government and EEAOs. I identify the energy efficient appliance organizational field as a bounded interorganizational network formed by organizations that participated in face-to-face 106 information-sharing conferences, negotiations on voluntary energy efficient appliance labeling, and negotiations on mandatory energy efficient appliance labeling. The network used in this study is constructed using archival data on organizational participation in face-to-face rulemakings, workshops, and conferences. The use of events to identify actors who have co-participated makes it a special kind of network called an affiliation or two-mode network. A two-mode network has information on both actors (the organizations) and the events that bring them together. In this affiliation network, we can observe l) ties between organizations through co-participation in events 2) ties between organizations and the events they participate in and 3) ties between events via organizational participation in multiple events (Faust, 2005). Two-mode data is beneficial as it forces us to think of how events that embody certain logics of appropriateness for influencing energy efficiency appliances bring organizations together and how organizations link these events together. Breiger (1974) points out that the duality of the data in affiliation networks allows one to analyze the relationships between an actor and its social grouping. Theoretically, an organization chooses to participate in an event based on shared logic(s), organizational affinities, or the ascribed status of the other organizational members participating in the event. At the same time, an organization’s pattern of participation in events influences its own points of references and organizational character. Studying organizational affiliation networks is useful because they reflect how organizational strategic choice and constraints combine to create the formation of networks. The social constraints are determined by the events that are offered in society whilst the meaning of these events is determined by the set of organizations that attend it. If nobody attends an 107 event, there is no social meaning. So in this sense, the dual examination of organization and events allows me to consider the interplay between agency and structure (Faust, 2005) Since organizations are choosing which events to attend, affiliation networks can be thought of as the pre-cursors to actual organizational relationships with each other and may provide insights into how these relationships form. The analysis Of two-mode data tells you not only who is exposed to whom (the precursor of direct organizational relationships or one mode data) but exactly which events brought them together. I hypothesize that the introduction and socialization of organizations (such as learning about each other’s activities and the emergence of tacit understandings or logics) at these events is often an important part of the process of forming direct organizational partnerships. Indeed, it is hard to imagine how partnerships form in the absence of such events. The events organizations participate in are specified in this study as an arena where organizations seek to influence the definition of the energy efficiency of residential appliances (specifically room air-conditioners, refrigerators/refrigerator-fi'eezers, clothes washers, and dishwashers). The events are either part Of l) mandatory energy efficiency standard rulemakings 2) voluntary energy efficiency label negotiations or 3) energy efficiency conferences that take place to inform the development of new voluntary or mandatory approaches. I understand organizational choices to participate in an event to be a decision to dedicate limited organizational resources of staff time and/or money and to be a reflection of an organization’s: l) perceived importance of the event in the defining and promoting appliance efficiency 2) acceptance of the legitimacy of the 108 event’s logic and purpose and 3) willingness of the organization to interact with the other organizations that attend/organize the event. Identification of cohesive non-overlapping subgroups in this network and the events they are meeting at recognizes that relationships and resources within an organizational field are textured. Campbell (2005) suggests that diffusion is one mechanism through which organizational fields can change. The amount organizations interact and the events they interact within determines their exposure to certain logics and the influence those logics hold over organizational actions. The content of the event exposes organizations in attendance to specific logics as well. I theorize that organizational and event subgroups are social locations within the organizational field where certain logics of appropriateness for who it is acceptable to partner with are developed and reinforced and that subgroup memberships will influence subsequent decisions to partner. To test this theory, I utilize a network influence model where organizational subgroup membership from 2001 to 2006 predicts subsequent decisions to co-author a paper with business for the field’s leading conference on energy efficiency in 2006 and 2008. This can be formalized as: Yit = PiWii’Yi’t-IW Yit-l +eit Yit represents the decision of energy efficiency advocacy organization i to cO-author with a business at time t (2006,2008). WYi’t—l indicates the relation between energy efficiency advocacy organization i and the subgroup it belongs to (i’) at time t-l (2001-2006) int-l represents the decisions of energy efficiency advocacy organization i to co-author with a business previous to H (1998, 2000) 109 eit is the error term where errors are assumed normal with mean zero and variance (02). Methods and Analysis Network Construction The study sought to construct a whole organizational network and was bound using an event-based approach (Marsden 2005). Events were identified by using archived information to identify organizations that had participated in face-to-face public activities of record that sought to influence the definition and promotion of residential energy-efficient appliances. Whole organizational networks are useful for “illuminating the structure of collective action” (Powell et al. 2005:1133). The activities were identified by the author, who previously worked in the field of appliance energy efficiency for three years, and through consultation with key leaders in non-profit and government agencies that work on appliance energy efficiency. They are limited to events that are of public record and that seek to influence the definition and promotion of an energy efficient appliance. Three classes of events were identified that organizations attended: 1) hearings for mandatory energy efficiency standards rulemakings 2) negotiations over voluntary energy efficiency specifications and 3) conferences seeking to inform the debates over appliance energy efficiency. The U.S. Department of Energy (DOE) is the agency charged with developing and implementing mandatory energy efficiency standards as enacted by the 1978 National Energy Conservation Policy Act (NECPA). For each rulemaking DOE is required to release an advanced notice of proposed rulemaking (ANOPR) that alerts stakeholders to its intention to make a standard and identify questions of interest for public input, a notice of proposed rule (NOPR) that puts for the agency’s proposed 110 standard and questions of interest for public input, and a final rule with the opportturity for stakeholder input. Each notice provides a time period for written public comments and attendance at public hearings (except for final rules). DOE is required to keep a docket with all those who submitted public comments during the commenting period and transcripts from the hearings with attendees and their organizational affiliation. Unfortunately, some materials from early dockets (1978 to 1993) were missing calling into question their entirety, but dockets from 1994 and on are fairly complete. From 1993 to 2000, I identify 7 DOE rulemaking hearings and 2 DOE rulemaking hearings from 2001 to 2006. In 1992, the Energy Policy Act directed the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to implement a program to identify and designate particularly energy efficient products and in 1993 the Energy Star program launched its first labeled products. In 1996, EPA and DOE became joint partners in Energy Star and the first voluntary specifications for refrigerators, room air conditioners, clothes washers and dishwashers were introduced (Webber, Brown and Koomey, 2000). From 2002 to 2006, the energy efficiency levels to be qualified as Energy Star were updated for multiple residential appliances and four face-to-face stakeholder workshops took place. In addition to these two government hosted sets of events, I utilized historic attendance at two sets of conferences that have sought to share information to, influence the definition of energy efficiency. The first, the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy’s (ACEEE) Summer Study on Energy Efficient Buildings, was initiated in1980 and has brought together a diverse group of professionals from around the world to discuss the technological basis for and practical implementation of 111 improving energy use in building with a consistent focus on appliance efficiency. This conference was organized initially by academics and professionals who felt that energy efficiency policy was not being well informed by scientific information. The second set of conferences is the Market Transformation Symposium, hosted jointly ACEEE and the Consortium for Energy Efficiency (CEE). Held in Washington DC. since 1997, this conference focuses mainly on market-based approaches to defining and promoting efficiency. This conference simultaneously serves as the Consortium for Energy Efficiency’s only public quarterly meeting for its members who develop voluntary appliance efficiency specifications to promote in their demand-side management programs. Attendees list were retrieved for all years of each of these sets of conferences resulting in the identification of 7 summer study conferences (4 from 1994-2000, and 3 from 2001-2006), and 10 market transformation symposium conferences (3 from 1994- 2000, and 6 from 2000-2006). The complete list of all organizations attending any of these events was then entered in a column and all events were entered across the top row to create an actor- event matrix. Where an organization attended an event, the number of organizational representatives attending was entered. All organizations were also coded with an organizational type using organizational listings (guidestar.org) or the organizational homepage on the internet. Organizational types identified were: 1) academic 2) federal government 3) international 4) national laboratory 5) non-profit energy efficiency advocacy 6) local, state, and regional government 7) regulated manufacturers 8) for-profit third party organizations (consultants) and 9) energy utilities. Associations of organizations were categorized in the organizational type that they represented. For 112 example, the Air-Conditioning and Refiigeration Institute, a trade association of air- conditioning and refrigerator manufacturers, was coded as a regulated manufacturer. Independent Variable: Cohesive Subgroup Membership To identify organizational subgroups within the affiliation data I utilized the recent adaptation of Frank’s (1995) clustering technique for identifying positions in two- mode data (Field, Frank, Schiller, Riegle-Crumb, Muller, 2006; Frank, Muller, Schiller, and Riegle-Crumb, 2008). Drawing on an extension of p* social network models to affiliation networks (Skvoretz and Faust 1999), the algorithm maximizes the increase in odds that an actor participates in an event within the same cluster versus participating in an event outside the cluster. When applied to the energy efficiency organizational field, the actors are energy efficiency advocacy organizations, the events are in-person meetings on defining appliance energy efficiency, and the identified clusters are local positions in which event attendance is concentrated. The benefits of the Kliquefinder algorithm are that it does not require the a priori assignment of connectedness criteria or number of groups required by other subgroup identifiers. It instead seeds groups based on strong connections and then moves organizations from group to group until it can not maximize the designated odds further. Kliquefinder was run for 2-mode data for the span of years from 1994-2000 and 2001-2006. From 1994 to 2000, a total of 37 EEAOs were included in the cohesive subgroups and 59 EEAOs were identified from 2001-2006. Organizations that were not included in the Kliquefinder subgroups, but only had one tie to an event were added back in to the subgroup that the event they attended was included in. The year spans were designated based on research that found that changes in political administrations influence the organizational relations between business and energy 113 efficiency advocates around energy efficiency appliance policy. The identified subgroups and organizational type groupings from each of these era’s networks was drawn in Netme 2-mode graphic representation. Independent Variable: EEAO decision to co-author a paper for summer study with business in 1 998-2000 Summer study conference proceedings from 1998 and 2000 are used to identify EEAOs that had cO-authored a paper. The types Of organizations they coauthored with are then coded into the nine organizational types described above. A binary variable was set up to code for if the EEAO had cO-authored with a utility or regulated manufacturer during this time period. This variable was used to control for previous EEAO decisions to co-author a paper in summer study with a business before exposure to events in their subgroup. Independent Variable: EEAO demographics Once all EEAOs in the subgroups were identified, organizational demographics were collected using a database of non-profit organizations (guidestar.org). The available revenues of the organization for each year from 2001 to 2006 derived from their I-99 tax form was recorded as an indicator of organizational size and resources. The average revenues of the organization was figured along with changes in revenue between 2001 and 2006. I hypothesize that organizations with fewer resources might be more likely to partner with a business organization out of need. The founding year of the organization was recorded and subtracted from 2006 to find the age of the organization. Age is used as an indicator of legitimacy (Hannah and Freeman 2004). Legitimacy could be important in either direction. Younger organizations may see partnering with business as 114 a way to gain legitimacy within institutional circles and in the eyes of specific firnders. Older, or more legitimate organizations, may be more able to partner with business without threatening their legitimacy within the energy efficiency advocacy community. Finally, organizational mission was derived from the mission statement provided either in the guidestar.org database or through reviewing the organizational web-page. Mission was coded as either environmental, energy, or consumer issues. Almost all organizations identify all three as motivations for improving energy efficiency, but the primary reason for the existence of the organization was used to determine the coding of the organizational mission. For example, Natural Resources Defense Council is an environmental group that works on energy issues and was coded as “environmental” whereas ACEEE is found solely as an energy efficiency group and was coded as “energy." Dependent Variables: EEAO decision to co-author a paper for summer study with business in 2006-2008 To assess the influence of organizational event attendance and group membership, I use co-authorship between an energy efficiency advocacy organization and a business organization (regulated manufacturer or energy utilities). The ACEEE summer study (also one Of the face-to-face events) publishes approximately 300-400 co-authored papers on energy efficiency every other year when it takes place. The conference began in 1980 with a small group of academics and national lab researchers presenting research findings to a select group of policymakers. The event has grown to be an industry-wide event for a wide range of organizations involved in energy efficiency to write up more applied research on the results of their efforts to promote efficiency. Organizational co- 115 authorship is often not only two organizations exploring an idea together, but a reflection Of a project that has already occurred. EEAOs and the Energy Efficiency Field Pre-2001: The Birth of Competing Logics Organizations to help people save energy have been around since the mid- twentieth century, finding its roots in the appropriate technology movement. One of the first, if not the first, was the Volunteers in Technical Assistance founded in 1959 by a group of scientists and engineers to help “low-income communities use more locally available and appropriate resources to meet their own needs for economic and social development” (Purcell, 2001). The appropriate technology movement, rooted in 1960’s counter-culture, embodied the idea that redistributive social justice goals could be reached by selectively using technology (Schnaiberg 1994; Purcell, 2001; Schumacher, 1970). When the 1973 oil crisis began, the number of these organizations began to grow at a rapid pace as the first larger concerted effort to conserve energy began to get popular support from local, state and federal governments (Purcell, 2001). Appropriate technology began its institutionalization with the establishment of Califomia’s Office of Appropriate Technology in 1976 that “sought to assist low-income groups and cultural minorities through the development Of human-scale technologies and ways Of thinking which promotes wise use of resources, more harmonious connections with the natural world, and smaller more workable government and social institutions” (Purcell, 2001:307-308). Starting in the late 1970’s, relatively separate from the appropriate technology movement, organizations and institutional mechanisms for influencing appliance energy efficiency emerge in dynamic mutual dependence. In 1975, the Energy Policy 116 Conservation Act established voluntary targets for appliance efficiency that were changed to mandatory standards in 1978. The American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE) was subsequently founded in 1979 by a group of academic and national lab energy efficiency researchers who had been working with limited success to inform mandatory standards at the state and federal level (Rosenfeld, 2000). In the original document drafted to recruit support for ACEEE, the nine-person founding committee, expressed the feeling that their individual voices needed to be expressed collectively through an organization to provide a counter-balance to the organized interests in supply-side solutions to One of the first tasks the founding committee identified was to “devise a way to disseminate this information [potential savings fi'om energy efficiency] broadly, to legislators at the federal, state, and local levels, and to technical and non-technical citizens throughout the country” (ACEEE, 1979:2). In 1980, to firlfill this goal, the first ACEEE study on energy efficiency was held in 1980 and has continued to be held bi-annually with participating growing and diversifying over the first decade. The beliefs underlying the founding of ACEEE and establishment of summer study can be characterized as a technocratic approach. Brulle (2000:235-237) writes that technocratic environmental reform organizations emphasize the role scientists have to play in the identification of problems and formation of solutions. The technocratic logic produces a hierarchy of technical knowledge and seeks to empower scientists. This is in contrast to earlier organizations in the appropriate technology movement that focused more on local direct engagement with the public to empower disadvantaged communities. In addition to influencing appliance efficiency through the provision of technical information for definitions, the passage of federal regulations (EPCA of 1978) provided 117 the opportunity for EEAOs to use legal tactics. Natural Resources Defense Council was founded in 1970 by a group Of lawyers, finding its origins in the logic that influencing the state’s development and enforcement of regulations through lawsuits was an effective tactic for protecting the environment. Building on its experiences in forcing the state to act on environmental regulations, NRDC brought the first set of lawsuits to force the Department of Energy under the Reagan administration to implement the appliance efficiency standards required by law. NRDC has continued to bring lawsuits (2001- 2006) in regards to appliance energy efficiency Often jointly with state attorney general’s offices and consumer rights groups. In the early 1990’s, another approach for defining and promoting energy efficiency by the state was born when the 1992 Energy Policy Act mandated that the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) develop a program to help American’s save energy and mitigate climate change. The Energy Star (ES) program was built upon ideas of social marketing and focused specifically on influencing consumer demand for efficient appliances. Although the Federal Trade Commission had been labeling appliances energy use for over a decade, Energy Star typically identifies that top 20% of energy performers of a product category on the market and labels it with a recognizable Energy Star seal. The first round of these voluntary standards was made with no formal input by stakeholders, instead relying mostly on agency assessments Of the markets and product availability and inforrna] consultation with stakeholders. This process changed in 2001 when DOE issued a voluntary specification for Energy Star windows in October 2001 that was highly protested by members Of the industry (McNary 2008). Lawsuits were threatened, and DOE had to start its analysis for the voluntary standard over in 118 spring of 2002, effectively delaying the implementation of the voluntary labeling program until fall of 2005. To avoid another instance of this, EPA and DOE implemented a more formalized and transparent public input process for the deciding what appliances would qualify for the Energy Star label. Following the trend towards market-based approaches, EEAOs also began to investigate how they could encourage manufacturers to produce more efficient appliances in ways other than command-and-control regulation. In the mid-1980’s David Goldstein, a physics graduate student of Arthur Rosenfeld (an ACEEE founder), joined the Natural Resources Defense Council’s (NRDC) energy program (Breckenridge, 2002). In the early 1990’s Goldstein pioneered the “golden carrot” approach to promoting energy efficiency. The approach focused on cooperative market-based approaches for promoting the development and sale of energy-efficient appliances through working with manufacturers and consumers. Regulatory mandatory standards were viewed as a way to “lock in” market shifts. The logic reflected in this approach is very characteristic of the cooperative business-environmental movement relations predicted by ecological modernization. In 1991, NRDC facilitated 24 utilities to pool their money to award a prize to the manufacturer that produced a marketable energy-efficient refrigerator. This project resulted in the creation of the Consortium for Energy Efficiency that seeks to facilitate utility support of energy-efficiency. Goldstein has also founded the Institute for Market Transformation (a small think-tank) and is president of the board of the New Buildings Institute. In 1997 ACEEE held the first market transformation symposium as a way to highlight the successes of the approach to improving energy efficiency and facilitate the spread of the approach. 119 The cohesive subgroups identified through organizational attendance of events from 1994 to 2000 provide a picture of an organizational field in flux as the groupings of events and organizations are difficult to interpret (Table 3.1 and Figure 3.1, Full organizational membership lists can be found in Appendix B). This could be attributed to the emergence of the Market Transformation Symposium in 1997. In group 1, all summer study conferences are linked together through the organizations that attend them. All academic organizations and the national labs (dominantly Lawrence Berkeley National Lab) are isolated from the rest of the organizational field besides their interactions with others through summer study. Groups 2 through 6 are made up of regulatory DOE hearings on mandatory standards and Market Transformation Symposiums. No particular pattern Of event groupings emerges from these linkages, but Figure 3.] identifies the organizational sectors that tie these events together. Lines between organizational sectors and subgroups indicate their attendance at those events and their role in linking events. The width of the line indicates the strength of their tie to the event as measured by the number of attendees sent to the event by organizations. Analysis of Figure 3.] reveals the central role that energy efficiency advocates, utilities, and regional government play in linking all types of events. Further analysis of individual organization’s connectedness to other organizations and events reveals that representatives of the state of California (California Public Utility Commission and California Energy Commission), NRDC, and ACEEE emerge as particularly central organizations that tie these conferences and rulemakings together. Another group that has strong links with both the summer study and market transformation conferences is 120 $.39 agree. 0 3:on “Boom Raouonwamuo . Enema—m 03850 e Eo>m o chasm $on m 920 880 Sasha: coco-o? o E 826 Heapsm aaOrie o8 \ v 98.0 spasm 82 NUEM v00.“ “vim mamfi Ega menusm 82 oopsm 88 2.3.33 ueu £38m 3:223...“qu can 35>”.— ..o anaewnam 9&8an "fin charm 121 Table 3.1: 1993-2000 Cohesive Subgroup Memberships 1993éitggiuogesrve Events Organizational Membership 1994 ACEEE Summer Study 11 academic organizations 1996 ACEEE Summer Study 4 federal government agencies 1998 ACEEE Summer Study 36 international organizations 2000 ACEEE Summer Study 5 national labs 1 16 local, state and regional government 1 regulated manufacturer 64 for-profit third party 22 power utilities 25 energy efficiency advocates 1999 ACEEE/CEE Market 1 federal government Transformation Symposium 2 international organizations 2000 ACEEE/CEE Market 6 local, state and regional 2 Transformation Symposium government 2 regulated manufacturers 25 for-profit third party 12 power utilities 10 energy efficiency advocates 1997 ACEEE/GEE Market 1 international organizations Transformation Symposium 3 local, state and regional 3 government 3 for-profit third party 7 power utilities 2 energy efficiency advocates January 1995 DOE Central Air- 1 regulated manufacturer Conditioning/Refrigerator 2 for-profit third party Rulemaking June 1998 DOE Central Air- 4 Conditioning/Refrigerator Rulemaking November 2000 DOE Central Air- Conditioning/Refrigerator RulemakinL December 1999 DOE Central Air- 1 federal government agency Conditioning/Refrigerator 3 energy efficiency advocates Rulemaking 2 local, state and regional 5 government 19 regulated manufacturers 13 for-profit third party 6 power utilities January 1994 Central air- 3 regulated manufacturers conditioning/refrigerator rulemaking February 1994 clothes washer rulemaking 6 September 1997 Central air- conditioning rulemaking November 1998 dishwasher rulemaking March 1998 ACEEE/GEE Market Transformation Symposium 122 for-profit consultants. As state and federal governments have cut their firll-time employees, consultants have played an increasingly important part in providing the technical expertise for assessing technologies, developing program designs, and implementing energy efficiency programs. In addition utilities utilize consultants to a large extent to implement their demand-side management programs. The Energy Efficiency Field 2001-2006: Organizational and Event Subgroups, Logics of Appropriateness, and Coauthorship Outcomes In examining the development of organizations and mechanisms for defining appliance efficiency prior to 2001, I identify four competing logics that guide the existence of these mechanisms and the events through which they are implemented: 1) the technocratic logic of the ACEEE summer study conferences 2) the regulatory logic ofDOE mandatory standard rulemakings 3) the consumer-based logic of EPA Energy Star negotiations and 4) the market transformation logic of the ACEEE/CEE market transformation symposiums. Each logic entails certain beliefs about who to work with or against in pursuing energy efficiency goals. The technocratic logic emphasizes the role of technical knowledge in defining appliance efficiency and emphasizes the importance of scientists and researchers. The regulatory logic emphasizes the role of regulations and emphasizes the importance of the state as mediator between the interests of EEAOs and business. Under a regulatory logic, business and EEAO interests are Often set up as counter to each other. Moving away from the regulatory approach, the consumer-based logic suggests that EEAO’s should work with the state and business to educate consumers. Finally, the logic of market transformation highlights the opportunity to partner with business to 123 develop and promote efficient products. These contradictory logics that guide partnering actions co-exist in the appliance energy efficiency organizational field. Organizations experience these contradictions as they participate in multiple kinds of events. To review, my theoretical understanding Of organizational choices to participate in an event to be a decision to dedicate limited organizational resources of staff time and/or money and to be a reflection of an organization’s: 1) perceived importance of the event in the defining and promoting appliance efficiency 2) acceptance of the legitimacy of the event’s logic and purpose and 3) willingness of the organization to interact with the other organizations that attend/organize the event. EEAO’s decisions to dedicate what are the often scarce resources of staff, money, and time should not be trivialized. Participation of EEAOs in these events is guided by a corresponding logic of appropriateness that reflects EEAO’s understandings of appropriate and effective actions for influencing the definition and promotion of energy efficiency residential appliances. The logics described above are reproduced and reinforced through organizational participation in different types of events. For example, organizations participating in regulatory events are enacting the regulatory logic in their decision to attend the event. Once at the event, the purpose and content of events along with exposure to other organizations that are adhering to the regulatory logic reinforces that participation in regulatory events is an effective way to influence appliance efficiency. Similarly, organizations attending the market transformation symposium with others who subscribe to the market transformation approach will strengthen their belief that the cooperative 124 market-based approaches emphasized in market transformation are appropriate and effective approaches tO improving appliance efficiency. Between the years of 2001 to 2006, four cohesive subgroups Of events and organizations emerge that reflect these logics. Each subgroup identifies a group Of organizations that are brought together by a group of events. The subgroups found in this time period unite events of the same type. All EPA Energy Star voluntary label negotiations are in group 1, DOE regulatory rule-makings are in group 2, all ACEEE/GEE market transformation symposiurns are in group 3, and all ACEEE Summer studies are in group 4 (Table 3.2, Full organizational membership lists from the cluster analysis can be found in Appendix B). The organizational membership of these cohesive subgroups identifies organizations that have stronger tendencies to attend certain kinds of events than others. Organizations still attend other kinds of events as well as illustrated in Figure 5.2. where, as with the earlier set of years examined, energy efficiency advocates, utilities, and for-profit consultants emerge at the center of the network linking all four types of events together. EEAOs are clustered mainly in two cohesive subgroups: 1) ACEEE summer study and 2) ACEEE/CEE market transformation symposium. I hypothesize that attendance at these two events predicts logics of appropriateness for partnering. Specifically I predict that organizations belonging to the market transformation group are more likely to enact a logic of market transformation and partner with businesses. To test this, I use organizational joint co-authorship Of papers for the ACEEE Summer study conference. The cohesive subgroups emerging from 2001-2006 contain 59 EEAOs. The cohesive subgroup’s organizational member’s annual revenues, organizational focus 125 Table 3.2: 2001-2006 Cohesive Subgroup Memberships 2001-2006 Cohesive Subgroups Events Organizational Membership July 2002 Refi'igerator/Freezer 2 energy efficiency advocacy organizations Energy Star Workshop 7 regulated manufacturers October 2004 Central Air- 4 for-profit third party organizations 1 Conditioner Energy Star Workshop 3 utility organizations August 2004 Clothes washer Energy Star Workshop July 2005 Dishwasher Energy Star Workshop March 2001 DOE Central air- 3 federal government agencies conditioning Rulemaking 4 energy efficiency advocacy October 2001 DOE Central air- organizations 2 conditioner Rulemaking 1 local, state and regional government 18 regulated manufacturers 5 for-profit third party organizations 6 power utilities 2002 ACEEE Summer Study 13 academic organizations 2004 ACEEE Summer Study 4 federal government agency 2006 ACEEE Summer Study 28 international organizations 4 national labs 3 27 energy efficiency advocacy organizations 13 local, state and regional government 98 for-profit third party organizations 25 power utilities 2001 ACEEE/CEE Market 1 federal government agency Transformation Symposium 25 energy efficiency advocacy 2002 ACEEE/CEE Market organizations Transformation Symposium 8 local, state and regional government 2003 ACEEE/CEE Market 4 regulated manufacturers 4 Transformation Symposium 25 for-profit third party organizations 2004 ACEEE/GEE Market 15 power utilites Transformation Symposium 2005 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium 2006 ACEEE/GEE Market Transformation Symposium and age can be found in Table 3.3. Independent samples t-test reveal that there is no significant difference in the organizational revenues and age of organizations in the Independent samples t-test reveal that there is no significant difference in the organizational revenues and age of organizations in the market transformation and 126 MCBDEEE mm. NSN BE mcémz‘ mm voom #53qu mm woom‘ museum .583. Eoéqu o , 3:833 v.03 Embocxnb . 04,3230 O Eo>m 9 LCDEEDEU .mcoanod x $2.9. EoEEwSOQ fiance m mum 4....m._..tcm 708‘ mm. mot... ...__..m2cw 94: E 5% ‘ flr_rut.:3Ew_Lr.,_/ :4; DE 2.4 P, 7.. g, TQC .. - - H E... 4.945 Ed. \/ 253 To _.Lm_._..._ .DESCQ r . 4 \ . Em 34$ 68‘ 96.1 :59: __.c._wcm¢ Ems/tar... , e: 3_H_m§\ .' Em .4.Emcm 33m 5; mac,” m I E or. 39%.. FEE: Um. ..._ 5; Son whim CS”. gin $2.33 new 288w 3:323...“qu was 3:95.— ue nascuwnsm 023.30 N m gnaw—m 127 Table 3.3: 2001-2006 Cohesive Subgroup Organizational Demographics Average Annual Revenues . Age (as of from 2001-200 6 Organizational Focus 2003) Cohesive 6.5 8.5-2.5 52.5-10 >510 C E . E < 5 >5 Subroups mill. mill. mill. mill. °“" “"'°° ""3" yrs. yrs. Consumer- Market 0 2 0 0 1 l 0 l 1 MT 1 10 1 1 4 2 5 19 9 l7 Refletory 0 l l l 2 1 0 1 2 Technocratic 5 9 9 5 4 13 11 12 16 Total Number 6 22 21 10 9 20 30 23 36 technocratic subgroups. In addition to revenues and age, organizations were coded for whether their primary mission focus of environment (identifying them as an environmental social movement organization), low-income or consumer issues, or energy. Although almost all groups referenced all three issues as a reason to advocate for energy efficiency, the primary reason for the organization’s existence was coded. Independent sample t-tests do reveal significant differences of organizational mission focus (p=.014, S.E.=.240) between the market transformation and technocratic subgroup with more energy groups in the market transformation group. In the years 1998 and 2000, a total of six EEAOs co-authored a paper for ACEEE summer study with either a utility company or a regulated manufacturer. In 2006 and 2008 this number had climbed to 16 EEAOs. Membership in the market transformation group also is a significant predictor of co-authorship with a regulated manufacturer or utility (p=.045, S.E.=.79) when controlling for an energy mission and previous co- authorship with business. Neither organizational revenues nor age was found to be significant predictors of organizational decisions to cO-author with business and were therefore dropped from the model. The odds of a member of the market transformation 128 logic group co-authoring a paper with a business are increased by approximately four than those not a member of the market transformation group. Table 3.4: Logistic Regression Results for Market Transformation Subgroup Membership and Business Co-authorship Variable Sigpit'lcance S.E. B Exp (B) 90-00 Co-authorship .0] 1* .99 2.52 10.08 Environ’l Mission .20] Consumer Mission .085 .10 -1.8 .166 Enfly Mission .502 1.21 .81 .445 MT Logic .045* .79 1.60 4.95 Discussion and Conclusions In this paper, I have sought to link the development of new events and organizations to the development and adoptions of new logics in an organizational field and subsequent organizational decisions to partner. The use of two-mode network analysis to identify cohesive subgroups of organizations and the events to bring them together advances our theoretical understanding of organizational fields by illuminating the texture of organization relations through identification of organizations that interact frequently in certain contexts. Through this more in-depth understanding of the organizational field, I am able to identify how uneven event and organizational exposure can lead to uneven adoption of certain logics of appropriateness for partnering and variation in subsequent partnering choices. I am able to illustrate that within the organizational field of appliance energy efficiency, organizations with a high level of embeddedness in market transformation events from 2001 to 2006 are more likely to co- author with businesses than those that are not. This paper does have limitations. I have not been able to control for all factors and although knowing co-authorship for the 1998 and 2000 years helps control for some firings, it can be argued that factors in flux between the two time periods have influenced 129 organizational co-authorship. A particular concern would be a shift in funding opportunities between 2000 and 2006. For example, if governmental agencies slashed funding, EEAOs may be more likely to seek business funding and consequently more likely to co-author. However, if this were the case, it does not explain why EEAOs in the two subgroups would experience funding changes differently. In addition tO providing insights on organizational and institutional change, this study can inform environmental sociological theories that deal with environmental social movements organizations and businesses relations. While political economic theories of the environment in environmental sociology identify the social and political factors that may influence social movement-business power relations, social movement organizations must interpret these changes and interpret appropriate actions in response. The case of energy efficient appliances identifies how one subgroup Of EEAOs has come to understand business organizations as appropriate and effective partners for pursuing their energy efficiency goals. The establishment of events that reproduce this logic, both in the organizations that participate in it (4 regulated manufacturers are part of the subgroup in contrast to the technocratic logic subgroup) and the content Of the event program, are one way that organizational fields are transformed and new institutional logics for action are enacted. This provides insight into how organizational fields formed around certain issues undergoes the process Of ecological modernization. 130 CONCLUSION Advancing Sociological Perspectives and Research on Organizations and the Environment The formal organization is the dominant organizing form for economic and social activities in modern society. These organizational activities are central in society’s production of environmental problems and its ability to mitigate and adapt in reaction to these problems. Environmental sociologists may be tempted to relegate the study of formal organizations to business schools, and business schools may be tempted to relegate the study of environmental problems to natural scientists, but not taking the relationships between formal organizations and the natural environment seriously in sociology is a disservice to sociology and hmnan and ecological health. This dissertation was an attempt to provide an initial example of the kind of productive sociological work that can be done at the intersection of organizational and environmental sociology. To reach my standards of an exemplary sociological piece of work at this intersection, it would incorporate all the lessons that I identify in my first article on strengthening sociological perspectives on organizations and the natural environment. Ideally, my first article suggests that my dissertation should demonstrate a more holistic approach to understanding 1) organizations as a product of their social and material environments 2) organizational impacts on the material environment 3) firm environmental behavior and its political economic context 4) cooperation and cooptation and 5) system constraints on organizational change. Unfortunately, in this dissertation I have not met all of these ideals of what a sociological study of organizations and the environment could truly accomplish, I hope that my contribution to understanding how 131 political economic theories of the environment and institutional theories of change are related can provide an example to build on for myself and others. Beginning my substantive look at the appliance energy efficiency field, my second article examined the structure of relations between government, business and civil society organizations around energy efficiency from 1973 to 2007 and the external factors that influence that structure of relationships. I illustrated that recognizing the broader sociopolitical conditions that alter societal power relations provides insight into when TOP or EMT theories are applicable. This article’s findings emphasized support for the importance of the state and the threat of regulation in determining relations between business, environmental, and government organizations. Employing a theory of the context dependent, I demonstrated that TOP theory is instructive in explaining power relations among state, business and civil society during the early Reagan years of first trying to regulate energy efficiency in residential appliances. However, EMT proved similarly useful for explaining more cooperative direct business-ESMO efforts to improve energy efficiency of appliances during the Clinton presidency. In my third article, I focused on the organizational processes underlying the emergence of cooperative business-social movement relations characterized by ecological modernization. This article highlighted how the changes in sociopolitical conditions discussed in the previous article led to organizational innovation and the creation of new events to influence energy efficiency. Organizational participation in these events created distinct organizational communities within the organizational field that led to the diffusion and adoption of new logics on who was an appropriate partner for pursing efficiency. In this article, I am able to demonstrate that energy efficiency advocacy 132 organizations embedded in the market transformation community from 2001 to 2006 were four times more likely to co-author a paper with a business organization than those not embedded in that community. Through this lens we get a slice of how in an organizational field where energy efficiency advocates battled with industry during the Reagan years (as predicted in TOP), some organizations adopted more cooperative approaches with industry to pursue their goals (as predicted in EMT). The major contribution my substantive study of the energy efficient appliance field makes is an advance in linking political economic theories Of the environment from environmental sociology to institutional change theories in organizational sociology. By identifying the organizational field as organized around a specific topic I am able to track business, governmental, and energy efficiency organization’s involvement in the issue and interaction with each other over time. A broader analysis of the sociopolitical conditions suggests that the presidential administration via openness to social movement attempts to regulate and the subsequent threat of regulation to businesses, influences changes in the relations between societal sectors. These changes in the sociopolitical environment result in changes in the effectiveness of various movement tactics for influencing energy efficiency. Four types of events for influencing energy efficiency reflect the development of competing logics of appropriateness for influencing efficiency and partnering: 1) technocratic where EEAOS work with researchers and scientists to produce and disseminate technical knowledge to policymakers and the public 2) consumer-based where EEAOs work with consumer groups 3) regulatory where EEAOs work via the state development of regulation and 4) market transformation where EEAOS work with industry on market-based approaches. This results in contradictory logics for 133 guiding action for partnering within the organizational field. Organizational interactions through events over time that reinforce certain logics results in the formation Of organizational subgroups. In this study, I demonstrate organizations belonging to the market transformation subgroup are more likely to cO-author with a business organization providing insight into how the process of ecological modernization occurs at the organizational field level. There is much to be done to improve our understanding beyond what I begin here. To create institutions that encourage positive environmental action, we must understand how contexts influence actions (Dietz, Ostrum, and Stern, 2004; Dietz and Henry, 2008). Further studies may continue what was begun in this research in the linking of macro and meso-level, a major challenge in the environmental social science (York, Rosa, and Dietz, forthcoming). Network analysis is a powerful tool for understanding the contexts of action by linking levels. Data limitations for this study made whole network measures difficult, but in the future with other sets of data, more could be said about the relations between societal sectors at the macro-level (Provan, Fish, and Sydow, 2007). Analysis of these societal sectoral networks can then be examined at the organizational level analysis. If data includes the people attending these events, analysis of individuals, their attendance at events, and their organizational affiliations over time could even be used to gain insight on the connection between the organizational and individual level. Developing these understandings can help develop new institutions for preserving the environment and aid those nonprofit, business, and governmental organizations involved in building institutions for a healthy and sustainable environment. 134 APPENDICES 135 APPENDIX A Full list of face-to-face meetings on the definition and promotion of energy efficient residential appliances available on public record from 1980 to 2006. 136 Table 1.1: Face-to-face meetings of available public record on appliance energy efficiency 1980-2006. DATE HOST TITLE July 1980 U.S. DOE ACEEE Summer Study Conference August 1980 ACEEE DOE Appliance Standard Rulemaking Hearig August 1982 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference ILugust 1984 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference Argust 1986 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference Augugt 1988 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference January 1989 DOE DOE Appliance Standard RulemakingHearing August 1990 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference August 1992 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference Central Air-Conditioning/Refrigerator-Freezer January 1994 US DOE Standard Rulemaking Hearing January 1994 U.S. DOE Clothes Washer Appliance Rulemaking HearinL August 1994 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference Central Air-Conditioning/ Refrigerator-Freezer January 1995 US DOE Standard Rulemaking Hearing August 1996 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference March 1997 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium September 1997 U.S. DOE gzrggzlgAIr-Condltlomng Test Procedure Revrsron March 1998 ACEEE/GEE Market Transformation Symposium Central Air-Conditioning/ Refrigerator-Freezer June 1998 U'S' DOE Standard Rulemaking Hearing August 1998 ACEEE Summer Study November 1998 U.S. DOE Dishwasher Test-Procedure Revision Hearing March 1999 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium Central Air-Conditioning / Refrigerator-Freezer December 1999 U.S. DOE Standard Rulemaking March 2000 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium November 2000 U.S. DOE Central Arr-Condltlomng / Refrrgerator- Freezer Standard Rulemakfl August 2000 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference March 2001 U. S. D OE Central Arr-Condltlonlng Test Procedure Revrslon Rulemakfl March 2001 ACEEE/GEE Market Transformation Symposium Central Air-Conditioning / Refrigerator-Freezer October 2001 U.S. DOE Standard Rulemaking March 2002 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium U.S. EPA /U.S. . July 2002 DOE Refrigerator-Freezer Energy Star Workshop August 2002 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference March 2003 ACEEE/GEE Market Transformation Symposium March 2004 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium U.S. EPA! U.S. August 2004 DOE Clothes Washer Energy Star Workshop August 2004 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study Conference U.S. EPA/ U.S. . . . October 2004 DOE Central Arr-Conditioner Energy Star Workshop March 2005 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium July 2005 U.S. EPA/U.S. DOE Dish Washer Energy Star Workshop March 2006 ACEEE/CEE Market Transformation Symposium August 2006 ACEEE ACEEE Summer Study 137 APPENDIX B Organizational and Event Subgroup Memberships 138 Table 3.5: Cohesive Subgroup Organizational and Event Membership for 1994- 2000. ORGANIZATIONAL ORGANIZATION TYPE SUBGROUP BuildingPerformance Institute, Inc. (BPI) energy efficiency advocates 1 California Urban Water Conservation Council energy efficiency advocates 1 Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers (AHAM) regulated manufacturer 1 BSH Home Appliances regulated manufacturer 1 Electrolux Inc. regulated manufacturer 1 Fisher & Paykel regulated manufacturer 1 General Electric Consumer Products muted manufacturer 1 Mamg Corporation Egrlated manufacturer 1 Whirlpool Corporation Egulated manufacturer 1 Air Conditioning Contractors of America (ACCA) third party consultant 1 National Energy Management Institute (N EMI) third party consultant 1 Procter & Gamble third party consultant 1 Sears, Roebuck & Company third party consultant 1 Alliant Enfly Corporation utility 1 Austin Water Utility utility 1 MidAmerican EnergyCompany utility l 2002/7/18 ESRRFWS Energy Star Workshop 1 2004/10/6 ESCACWS Energy Star Workshop 1 2004/8/15 ESCWWS Energy Star Workshop 1 2005/7/13 ESDWWS EnegyStar Workshop 1 Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) federaljovemment 2 National Institutes of Standards and Technology (N IST) federal government 2 American Association of Retired Persons, Consumer Issues energy efficiency advocates 2 Appliance Standards Awareness Project (ASAP) enegy efficiency advocates 2 Center for Enfly & Environment energy efficiency advocates 2 Consumer Federation of America energy_efficiency advocates 2 Northwest Power PlanninLCouncil enfly efficiency advocates 2 City of Austin regional government 2 Air Conditioning & Refrigeration Institute (AR1)- now Air Conditioning, Heating and Refi'igeration (AHRI) regulated manufacturer 2 Allied Signal, Inc. re lated manufacturer 2 Armstrong Air Conditioning, Inc. regulated manufacturer 2 Bard ManufacturiggCo. regulated manufacturer 2 139 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Carrier Corporation/United Technologies regulated manufacturer 2 Copeland Corporation regulated manufacturer 2 ECR International, Inc. re ulated manufacturer 2 Gas Appliance Manufacturers Association, InflGAMA) rgggted manufacturer 2 Goodman Manufacturing Company, LP. (Amana) regulated manufacturer 2 Hydrotherrn Corporation, A Mestek Inc. Company regflted manufacturer 2 International Comfort Products Corporation regulated manufacturer 2 Lennox International Inc. rggulated manufacturer 2 Modine Manufacturing Company regulated manufacturer 2 Nordyne Co. regulated manufacturer 2 Rheem Manufacturing Company regyirted manufacturer 2 Trane Company/American Standard regulated manufacturer 2 Unico System regulated manufacturer 2 York International Corporation regulated manufacturer 2 Energy Design Update third party consultant 2 GPU Service Co. third party consultant 2 Intertek Testing Services third party consultant 2 Systematic Mange_ment Services, Inc. third party consultant 2 Wiley, Rein, & Fieldirg third party consultant 2 Baltimore Gas & Electric utility 2 Edison Electric Institute (EEI) utility 2 Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI) utility 2 National Rural Electric Cooperative Association utility 2 Pepco Holdings, Inc. utility 2 Virginia Power utility 2 2001/10/2CACRMWS DOE Rulemaking He% 2 2001/3/29CACTPWS DOE Rulemaking-harm 2 Brooks Energy& Sustainability Laboratory academic 3 California Lighting Techno—logy Center academic 3 California State University academic 3 Cameg Mellon University academic 3 Oberlin Coljge academic 3 Portland State University academic 3 Princeton University academic 3 Purdue University academic 3 Texas A&M University academic 3 University of California academic 3 140 Table 3.5 (cont’d) University of Colorado academic University of Washin on academic Washinglon State University academic National Aeronautics and Space Center (NASA) federal government 3 U.S. Cmss federalgovemment 3 U.S. Department of EngggUS. DOEL federal government 3 U.S. Department of Housing & Urban Development (HUD) federal gpvemment 3 Australian Greenhouse Office international 3 BRANZ Ltd. international 3 Center for Energy Efficiency - EnEffect international 3 Central European University international 3 Central Research Institute of Electric Power Industry (CRIEPI) international 3 Central Research Institute of Electric Power Industry (CRIEPI), Japan international 3 Chalmers University of Technology, Sweden international 3 China Ceritifcation Center for Energy Conservation Product (CECP) international 3 China National Institute of Standardization international 3 Danish Building Research Institute international 3 Danish Energy Management A/S international 3 Enegy Efficient Strategies, Australia international 3 Enova SF international 3 European Commission Directorate international 3 EVO international 3 Hydro Quebec international 3 Jyunkankyo Research Institute, Tokyo international 3 Linkopinggniversity international 3 Manitoba Hydro international 3 Minisgy of Construction, China international 3 National Research Council Canada international 3 Natural Resources Canada international 3 NOVEM international 3 Osaka Gas international 3 Osaka University international 3 Regulatory Authority for Electricity & Gas, Italy international 3 United Nations international 3 University of Toronto international 3 Lawrence Berkeley National Laborato (LBNL) ‘ national lab 3 I41 Table 3.5 (cont’d) National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL) national lab 3 Oak Ridge National Laboratory (ORNL) national lab 3 Pacific Northwest National Laboratory QNNL) national lab 3 Academy for Educational Development (AED) energy efficiency advocate 3 Academy for Educational Development (AED) energy efficiency advocate 3 Advanced Energy Corporation energy efficiency advocate 3 Advanced Energy Corporation energy efficiency advocate 3 Affordable Comfort, Inc. (AC1) energy efficiency advocate 3 Affordable Comfort, Inc. (AC1) energy efficiency advocate 3 Association for Energy Affordability, Inc. (AEA) energy efficiency advocate 3 Association for Energy Affordability, Inc. (AEA) energy efficiency advocate BuildingCodes Assistance Project (BCAP) energy efficiency advocate California Climate Action Registry energy efficiency advocate California Home Energy Efficiency Rating S stem energy efficiency advocate 3 California Institute for Energy Efficiency LCIEE) energy efficiency advocate Center for Neighborhood Technology (CNT) energy efficiency advocate Clean Air - Cool Planet energy efficiency advocate Collaborative Labelling and Appliance Standards Program (CLASP) energy efficielgy advocate 3 Community Enhancement Services energy efficiency advocate 3 Ecology Action energy efficiency advocate 3 Efficient Windows Collaborative energy efficiency advocate 3 Electric Solar Utility Network (ElectricSUN) energy efficiency advocate 3 Electricity Innovation Institute energy efficiency advocate 3 Energy Center of Wisconsin (ECW) energy efficiency advocate 3 Enfly Conservation Finance Institute (ECFI) energy efficiency advocate 3 Energy Foundation energy efficiengy advocate 3 EnergyTrust of Oregon (ETO) energy efficiency advocate 3 Florida Solar Energy Center energy efficiency advocate 3 Global Environment & Technology Foundation energy efficiency advocate 3 Institute for Market Transformation energy efficiency advocate 3 International Energy Agency (IEA) energy efficiency advocate International Institute for Energy Conservation (IIEC) enemy efficiency advocate Iowa Energy Center energy efficiency advocate Lighting Research Center, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute QsRC) energy efficiency advocate Lower Colorado River Authority (LCRA) energLefficiency advocate 142 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDQ energy efficiency advocate 3 Northeast States for Coordinated Air Use Management (N ESCAUM) entfly efficiency advocate 3 Northwest Power & Conservation Council erflgy efficiency advocate 3 Pacific Institute enigy efficiency advocate 3 Pew Charitable Trusts energy efficiency advocate 3 Portland Energy Conservation, Inc. (PECI) energy efficiency advocate 3 Eulatoq Assistance Project (RAP) energy efficiency advocate 3 Residential Energy Services Network (RESNET) energy efficiency advocate 3 Sierra Club energy efficiency advocate 3 Southern Alliance for Clean Buggy enmefficiency advocate Southwest Energy Efficiency Partnerships (SWEEP) energmficiency advocate 3 U.S. Green Building Council (USGBC) energy efficiency advocate 3 Bonneville Power Administration (BPA) regional government 3 California Energy Commission (CEC) regionemmem 3 California Public Utility Commission regional government 3 City of Boulder regional Qvemment 3 City of Lompoc regional government 3 City of San Francisco regional government 3 City of Santa Monica regional government 3 New Jersey Board of Public Utilities regional government 3 Ohio Office of Consumers' Council regional government 3 Oregon Office of Energy regional government 3 Vermont Department of Public Service regionaljovemment 3 Western Area Power Administration (WAPA) regional government 3 Wisconsin Energy Bureau regional government 3 Alternative Energy Systems Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Appliance Recycling Centers of America, Inc. (ARCA) third party consultant 3 Architectural Energy Co. (ABC) third party consultant 3 Amp third party consultant 3 ASW Engineering third party consultant 3 Better Buildings Interactive third party consultant 3 Bevilacqua-Knight, Inc. third party consultant 3 Building Science Corporation third party consultant 3 Cardinal 10 third party consultant 3 CH2M Hill third party consultant 3 CMC Eflgy Services third party consultant 3 Consol, Inc. third party consultant 3 Davis Energy Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 143 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Demand Research third party consultant 3 Dethman & Associates third party consultant 3 Dunlap & Browder, Inc. third party consultant 3 Dunsky Energy Consulting third party consultant 3 DuPont third party consultant 3 Duro-Last Roofing Inc. third party consultant 3 ECONorthwest third party consultant 3 Boos Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Ecotope, Inc. third party consultant 3 Eley Associates third party consultant 3 Erflgy & Resource Solutions, Inc. third party consultant 3 Energy Conservatory third partyconsultant 3 Energy Market Innovations, Inc. third party consultant 3 Energy Solutions Unltd. third party consultant 3 EnVinta Corp. third party consultant 3 Equipoise Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 E-SOURCE/Platts third party consultant 3 Etc. Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 Franklin Energy Services, Inc. third party consultant 3 Freeman & Associates, LLC third party consultant 3 Freeman, Sullivan & Co. third party consultant 3 Frontier Associates third party consultant 3 Geltz Communications third party consultant 3 GeoPraxis, Inc. third party consultant 3 Gruenreich Resource Advocate third party consultant 3 H. Gil Peach & Associates LLC third party consultant 3 Heschong Mahone Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 HMW International, Inc. third party consultant 3 Home Building Technology Services third party consultant 3 Home Energy Magazine third party consultant 3 IBACOS, Inc. third party consultant 3 Ice Energy LLC third party consultant 3 Innovologie, LLC thirdJarty consultant 3 Invensys third party consultant 3 Itron, Inc. third party consultant 3 KEMA, Inc. third party consultant 3 KEMA-XENERGY, Inc. third party consultant 3 KJ Consultifl third party consultant 3 kW Engineering third party consultant 3 Loisos & Ubbelohde Associates third party consultant 3 144 Table 3.5 (cont’d) ‘flgdal & Associates third pagyconsultant 3 MOjan MarketingPartners, LLC third party consultant 3 Nagigant Consultinfilnc. third party consultant 3 Nexant, Inc. third party consultant 3 North American Insulation Manufacturers Association (NAIMA) thirgpany consultant 3 North American Technician Excellence (NATE) third party consultant 3 Optimal Energy, Inc. third party consultant 3 Orion Energy Systems, Ltd. third paLty consultant 3 Owens Corning third party consultant 3 PA ConsultigGroup, Inc. third party consultant 3 Performance Systems Development, Inc. third party consultant 3 Peter Benenson Consulting third party consultant 3 Peter Schwartz & Associates third party consultant 3 Potomac Resources, Inc. third party consultant 3 Prahl & Associates third party consultant 3 Proctor Engineering Group, Ltd. third party consultant 3 Quantec, LLC third party consultant 3 Quantum Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Michal Economic Research, Inc. third party consultant 3 Research Into Action, Inc. third party consultant 3 Rita Norton & Associates, LLC third party consultant 3 RLW Analytics, Inc. third party consultant 3 Robert Mowris & Associates third party consultant 3 SBW Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Schiller Associates third party consultant 3 Science Applications International Co. (SAIC) third party consultant 3 She] Feldman Management Consultants (SFMC)) third party consultant 3 Sheltersource, Inc. third party consultant 3 Skumatz Economic Research Associates, Inc. third party consultant 3 Steven Winter Associates, Inc. third party consultant 3 Strategic Energy Technologies, Inc. third party consultant 3 Summit Blue Consulting LLC third party consultant 3 Sustainable Energy Partnerships third party consultant 3 Synapse Energy Economics, Inc. thirdgrarty consultant 3 TecMRKT Works LLC third party consultant 3 TIAX, LLC third party consultant 3 TRC Eneggy Services third party consultant 3 Truveon Co. third party consultant 3 Valley Energy Efficiency Co. third party consultant 3 145 Table 3.5Lcont’d) Vermont Enegy Investment Co. (VEIC) third party consultant 3 Vistron Corp. third party consultant 3 Weidt Group third party consultant 3 Wirtshafter Associates, Inc. third pary consultant 3 Xenergy, Inc. third party consultant 3 Yinsight third party consultant 3 AQUILA utility 3 British Columbia Gas Utility Ltd. utility 3 British Columbia Hydro utility 3 Community Energy Cooperative utility 3 Enbridge Gas Distribution utility 3 EW utility 3 _Et_l_gene Water & Electric Board utility 3 Nevada Power Company utility 3 Northwest Natural Gas Company utility 3 Oncor Energy utility 3 Pacific Gas & Electric Company utility 3 Portland General Electric Company utility 3 flget Sound Energy (PSE) utility 3 Sacramento Municipal Utility District (SMUD) utility 3 Salt River Project (SRP) utility 3 San Diego Gas & Electric Co. (SDG&E) utility 3 Seattle City Light utility 3 Sierra Pacific Power Company utility 3 Southern California Edison Company (SCE) utility 3 Southern California Gas Company utility 3 Tacoma Power utility 3 TXU Electric Company utility 3 We Energies utility 3 Western Massachusetts Electric Co. (WMECO) utility 3 Xcel Energy, Inc. utility 3 2002 SS Summer Study Conference 3 2004 SS Summer Study Conference 3 2006 SS Summer Study Conference 3 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (U SEPA) federal government Alliance to Save Energy energy efficiency advocate American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE) enegy efficiency advocate 4 Consortium for Energy Efficiency, Inc. (CEE) enegy efficiency advocate 4 146 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Economic Opportunity Research Institute energyefficiency advocate 4 Efficiency Vermont energy efficiency advocate 4 Energy and Environmental Building Association (EEBA) energy efficiency advocate 4 EnergLCoordinatingAgency of PA, Inc. energLefficiency advocate 4 Energy Federation, Inc. energy efficiency advocate 4 Marketing Science Institute energLefficiency advocate 4 Midwest Energy_Efficiency Alliance (MEEA) energy efficiency advocate 4 National Albanian American Council energyefficiency advocate 4 National Center for Energy Management and Buildifl Technologies (NCEMBT) enggyefficiency advocate 4 National EnggLFoundation enfiy efficiency advocate 4 Natural Resources Council of Maine energy efficiency advocate 4 New Buildingsilnstitute, Inc. (NBI) energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Energy Efficiency Council energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Energy Efficiency Partnerships, Inc. (N EEP) energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Midwest Institute energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Power PlanningCouncil energy efficiency advocate 4 Northwest Energy Efficiency Alliance (N EBA) energy efficiency advocate 4 Northwest Energy Efficiency Council energy efficiency advocate 4 Rocky Mountain Institute (RMI) energy efficiency advocate 4 Technical Development Corporation enfly efficiency advocate 4 Vermont Energy Investment Corporation energy efficiency advocate 4 Wisconsin Energy Conservation Corporation/ Focus on Energy energy efficiency advocate 4 District of Columbia Public Service Commission regionaljovemment 4 Idaho Public Utilities Commission regionaljovernment 4 Maine Public Utilities Commission regional government 4 Maryland Energy Administration regionalglvemment 4 Massachusetts Division of Enegy Resources regional gpvemment 4 New York State Energy Research & Development Authority (NYSERDA) regional government 4 Ohio Department of Development regioflgovemment 4 Ohio Office of Energy Efficiency regional government 4 Effikal International, Inc. re lated manufacturer 4 Flowserve Corp. Mad manufacturer 4 Good Earth Lighting regulated manufacturer 4 Honeywell, Inc. regulated manufacturer 4 147 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Applied Proactive Technologh Inc. (APT) third party consultant 4 Aspen Systems Co. third party consultant 4 Cadmus Group, Inc. third party consultant 4 Conservation Services Group, Inc. (CSG) third party consultant 4 Copper Develgpment Association Inc. third party consultant 4 D & R International Ltd. third party consultant 4 EAM Associates, Inc. third party consultant 4 ERG International, Inc. third party consultant 4 GDS Associates, Inc. third party consultant 4 flggman Inc. third party consultant 4 Hydraulic Institute third party consultant 4 ICF Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 4 I'I‘T Industrial Products Corp. third party consultant 4 LDL Consulting third party consultant 4 Lockheed Martin Aspen Systems third party consultant 4 Magrann Associates third party consultant 4 Marketing Drive Worldwide third party consultant 4 MCN third party consultant 4 National Association of Energy Service Companies (NAESCO) third party consultant 4 National Electrical Manufacturers Association (NEMA) third party consultant 4 Nexus 13%, Inc. third party consultant 4 North American Retail Dealers Association (NARDA) third party consultant 4 Northeast by Northwest third party consultant 4 Opinion Dynamics Corporation third party consultant 4 Pacific Energy Associates, Inc. third party consultant 4 PR third party consultant 4 Resource Planning Group third party consultant 4 Schlegel & Associates third party consultant 4 SENTECH, Inc. third party consultant 4 Servidyne Systems, LLC third party consultant 4 TraynorKirk and Co. third party consultant 4 Wisconsin Energy Conservation Corp.(WECC) third party consultant 4 Austin Energy utility 4 Center Point Enegy utility 4 Conectiv Power Delivery utility 4 Georgia Power Co. utility 4 Jersey Central Power & Light utility 4 Keyspan Energy Corp. utility 4 148 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Long Island Power Authority (LIPA) utility 4 National Grid USA utility 4 New Hampshire Electric Cooperative, Inc. utility 4 Northeast Utilities utility 4 NSTAR Electric & Gas utility 4 Public Service Electric & Gas Company (PSE&G) utility 4 South Jersey Gas Company utility 4 United Illuminatig Co. utility 4 Vermont Gas Systems, Inc. utility 4 Market Transformation 2001MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2002MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2003MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2004MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation ZOOSMT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2006MT Symposium 4 American Association for the Advancement of Science (AAAS) academic No Group City University of New York (CUNY) academic No Group Cornell University academic No Group Daylighting Lab academic No Group George Mason University academic No Group Green Mountain College academic No Group Hong-Ik University academic No Group Howard University academic No Group Kansas State University academic No Grog Michign State University academic No Grog: National Center for Atmospheric Research (NCAR) academic No Group Oregon Renewable Energy Center academic No Group Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute academic No Group Umea University academic No Group University of Alaska academic No Group University of Delaware academic No Group University of Idaho academic No Grgp 149 Table 3.5 (cont’d) 150 University of Illinois academic No Group University of Maryland academic No Group University of Michigan academic No Group University of Nevada academic No Group University of North Carolina academic No Group Vermont Law School academic No Group U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID) federal government No Group U.S. Department of Agriculture (DOA) federal government No Group U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) federal ggernment No Group U.S. General Services Administration federal government No GrouL Agencia Nacional de Energyia Electrica (ANEEL) international No Group Beijing Association of Sustainable Development international No Group Beijing Electric Light Sources Research Institute international No Group Beijing Energy Efficiency Center international No Group Berliner Energieagentur Ltd. international No Group Big Switch Projects international No Group Butwal Power Company P. Ltd. international No Group Carbon Trust international No Group Centre for Renewable Energy Systems Technology international No Group Cete de Lyon international No Group CFL Harmonisation Initiative international No Group China Sustainable Energy Program international No Group Commergy Ltd. international No Group Danish Electricity Saving Trust Fund international No Group Danish Energy AgencL international No Group Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs aka Senternovem international No Group E.V.A. the Austrian Energy Agency international No Group Ecole des Mines de Paris international No Group Econoler International international No Group Efficiency NB international No Group Eletrobras/Procel international No Group Energy Efficiency and Conservation Authority international No Group Energy Research Institute, China international No Group Exergy Australia Pty Ltd international No Group Golden Power Manufacturing, Ltd. international No Group Government of Canada international No Group Housing & Building Research Center (HBRC), Egypt international No Group Table 3.5 (cont’d) IEI international No GYM IFZ - Inter-University Research Center international No Group IIEU international No Group Industrial Technology Research Institute (ITRI) international No Group Institut fur Engrgie und Umweltforschung international No Group Institute of Local Government Studies (AKF) international No Group Instituto de lnvestiggiones Electricas international No Group Joint Research Centre of the European Communities international No Group Kerma, Inc. international No Group Korea Gas Co.. international No Group Korea Institute of Energy Research (KIER) international No Group Kyushu University, Japan international No Group LivingWise international No Group Mexican Energy Saving National Commission CONAE international No Group Mid Sweden University international No Group National Development & Reform Commission, China international No Group NCC Nordic Construction Company international No Group Ontario Power Technologies international No Group PROCEL/Eletrobras international No Group Royal Nepal Academy of Science and Technology (RONAST) international No Group Saskatchewan Research Council international No Group Shanghai Energy Conservation Supervision Center international No Group Shanghai HousigDevelopment Bureau international No Group Sietten Finnmark AS international No Group State Economic & Trade Commission international No Group Surya Roshni international No Group Technical University of Denmark international No Group Terasen Gas international No Group Tokyo University intemational No Grog Trilogy Holdings, Ltd. international No Group U.K. Market Transformation Program international No Group _Uganda Christian University Mukono international No Group University of British Columbia international No Group University of Kassel international No Group University of New South Wales international No Group University of Twente international No Group University of Waterloo international No Group 151 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Victoria University of Wellington international No Group Brookhaven National Laboratory national lab No Group Idaho National Engineering & Environment Laboratory national lab No Group Electric Solar Utility Network (ElectricSUN) energy efficiency advocate No Group Environmental & Energy Study Institute (EESI) academic No Group eProcurement Project energy efficiency advocate No Group Focus on Energy energy efficiency advocate No Group Four Winds Resource and Conservation Area energy efficiency advocate No Group International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives (ICLEI) energy efficiency advocate No Group Kentucky Pollution Prevention Center energy efficiency advocate No Group National Commission on Energy Policy energLefficiency advocate No Group Northeast Premium Efficiency Motor Initiative enegyefficiency advocate No Group PATH energy efficiency advocate No Group Vermont Campus Energy Group energy efficiency advocate No Group Virginia Housing& Environment Network energy efficiency advocate No Group WestEd energy efficiency advocate No Gropp Arkansas State Energy Office regional government No Group Avondale regional grvemment No Group California Department of General Administration regional government No Group Champlain Valley Office of Economic Opportunity (CVOEO) regional government No Group City of Berkeley regional government No Group City of Oakland regional government No Group City of Palo Alto regional government No Group City of Pleasanton regional government No Group City of San Jose regional government No Group City of Seattle regionngovemment No Group City of Springfield Egional government No Group Georgia Environmental Facilities Authority regional government No Group Idaho Department of Resources reflmalgpvernment No Group Indiana Consumer Advocate Office regional government No Group Inland Empire Utilities Agency regional government No Group Iowa Department of Justice, Office of Consumer Advocate regional government No Group Kentucky Office of Energy Policy regional government No Group Louisville Metro Air Pollution Control District remnalgwemment No Group Maine State Planning Office regional government No Group Massachusetts Board of Building Regulations and Standards regional government No Group 152 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Missouri Buggy Center regional grvernment No Group Moorhead Public Service Department Egional gpvemment No Group National Association of State Energy Offices ASEO) regional government No Group New Hampshire Public Utilities Commission Mal government No Group North Carolina Department of Commerce regional government No Group Public Service Commission of Wisconsin rgional government No Group San Diego County Water Authority regipnaIfl/emment No Group San Diego Regional Energy Office regional government No Group San Francisco Public Utilities Commission re ional government No Group Seattle Public Utilities regional fivernment No Group Snohomish County Public Utilities Commission regional government No Group Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) regionaigovernment No Group Utah Enggy Office regional government No Group A.O. Smith Co. regfled manufacturer No Group Absocold regulated manufacturer No Group Advanced Conservation Technologies, Inc. (ACT) Metlund Systems regulated manufacturer No Group Amana Refrigeration Inc. regrlated manufacturer No Group American Fluorescent regulated manufacturer No Group Climate Master regulated manufacturer No Group Emerson Motor Co regulated manufacturer No Group Flanders Electric of IL regulated manufacturer No Group Goulds Pumps - ITT Industries regulated manufacturer No Group Haier regulated manufacturer No Group Marcelo regulated manufacturer No Group Marvel Industries regulated manufacturer No Group Microfridge regulated manufacturer No Group Miele regulated manufacturer No Group National Comfort Products regulated manufacturer No Group Philips Lighting Co. Egulated manufacturer No Group Samsung Air Conditioners regulated manufacturer No Group Space Pak regulated manufacturer No Group Staber Industries regulated manufacturer No Group Sun Frost regulated manufacturer No Group U-Line Corporation regulated manufacturer No Group Ultra 8 International / Ariston Appliances Egulated manufacturer No Group United Technologies Research Center ggulated manufacturer No Group W. C. Wood Company Limited regulated manufacturer No Group ADM Associates, Inc. third party consultant No Group Aeroseal third party consultant No Group 153 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Afterimagg + Sgace third party consultant No Group Air Conditioning, Heating & Refrigeration News third party consultant No Group Alewife Energy & Environment third party consultant No Group All Star Construction third party consultant No Group American Gas Association (AGA) third party consultant No Group American Lighting Association (ALA) third party consultant No Group American Synergy Co. third party consultant No Group Applied EnergLResearch Group third party consultant No Group Applied Engineering ManaLment third party consultant No Group AJplch Flow Technolgy third party consultant No Group Applied Innovations Research third party consultant No Group Applied Resources Group thirdparty consultant No Group Arthur D. Little, Inc.(ADL) third party consultant No Group Association of Energy Service Professionals (AESPL third party consultant No Group ATOFINA Chemicals, Inc. thirdparty consultant No Group Ayala Land Inc/Ayala Property Mgt. Corp. third party consultant No Group Bayview Technology Group third party consultant No Group BeckleLSingleton, Cntd. third party consultant No Group Benya Lighting Design third party consultant No Group Berkeley Solar Group third party consultant No Group Bozell Kamstra third party consultant No Group Braebum Systems third party consultant No Group Bramante Energy, Inc. third party consultant No Group Brand Source - AVB third party consultant No Group Buderus Hydronic Systems third party consultant No Group Business & Energy Services third party consultant No Group Calyx Investments third party consultant No Group Caneta Research, Inc. third party consultant No Group Cannon Technologies third party consultant No Group Chitwood Energy Management third party consultant No Group Chong Partners Architecture third party consultant No Group Chris Robertson & Associates, LLC third party consultant No Group CLEAResult Consulting, Inc. third party consultant No Group Climate Energy, LLC third party consultant No Group Comfort Diagnostics & Solutions third party consultant No Group Competitive Resources, Inc. third party consultant No Group Concurrent Technologies Corp. third party consultant No Group Consumer Powerline third party consultant No Group Costco third party consultant No Group 154 Table 3.5 (cont’d) CS&M Marketing third party consultant No Group CT C third party consultant No Group Curtiss-mht EMD third party consultant No Group Dawnbreaker third party consultant No er Design AVEnues third party consultant No Group Eastern Research Group third party consultant No Group Ed Malemezian Consulting Inc. third party consultant No Group Electrical Apparatus Service Association third party consultant No Group Electronic Industries Alliance third party consultant No Group Elemental Enterprises third party consultant No Group Elf Atochem North America, Inc. third party consultant No Group Enercomp, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energetics, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy & Environmental Management Magazine third party consultant No Group Energy and Environmental Economics, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy Economics, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy Market & Policy Analysis, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy Saving Products, Ltd. third party consultant No Group Enemet Co. third party consultant No Group _Erlgineered Web Information Systems third party consultant No Group Envenergy third party consultant No Group Environmental Interface, Ltd. third party consultant No Group Esherick Homsey Dodge & Davis third party consultant No Group ETW Inc. third party consultant No Group F. Smothers & Associates third party consultant No Group First Tracks Consulting Service, Inc. third party consultant No Group Florida Home Energy & Resources _nganization (HERO) third party consultant No Group Flowcare Eflineering Inc. third party consultant No Grog) Frito-Lay third party consultant No Group GH Consultig, LLC third party consultant No Group Global Energy Options third party consultant No Group Global Ermy Partners, LLC third party consultant No Group Green Homes America third party consultant No Group Green Order third party consultant No Group Grimason Associates, LLC third party consultant No Group Gunnar Hovstadius Consulting, LLC. third party consultant No Group Habart & Associates Consultingfl. third party consultant No Group Halton Company third party consultant No Group Harris Design Inc. third party consultant No Group 155 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Hatch Consultifi third party consultant No Group HEC, Inc. third party consultant No Group Hill and Knowlton third party consultant No Group Hoffman Corporation third party consultant No Group Hoffman LLCNertegy third party consultant No Group Hoffman York third party consultant No Group Home Depot third party consultant No Group Home Excellence, Inc. third party consultant No Group HPAC Engineering third party consultant No Group lcynene Co. third party consultant No Group Innovest Strategflalue Advisors third party consultant No Group INSIGHT third partyconsultant No Group Insights Unlimited third party consultant No Group Igtegrated DeflgpAssociates, Inc. third party consultant No Group Interbrand third party consultant No Group J. Ottrnan Consulting third party consultant No Group Jaco Environmental third party consultant No Group Jim Perich-Anderson ConsultinL third party consultant No Grog John Manville third party consultant No Group KAT Consulting third party consultant No Group KER] third party consultant No Group Koeller & Company third party consultant No Group Lambert Engineering, Inc. third party consultant No Group Les Tumidaj & Associates third party consultant No Group Levy Associates third party consultant No Group Lighting Wizards third party consultant No Group LumenX, Inc. third party consultant No Group Lutron Electronics Co., Inc. third party consultant No Group MaxLite third party consultant No Group Mintz, Levin, Cohn, Ferris, Glovsky and Popeo, P.C third party consultant No Group Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc. third party consultant No Group MSI Consulting third pagy consultant No Group Mullen Advertising third party consultant No Group National Association of Home Builders (N AHB) third party consultant No Group National Association of Plumbing Heating Cooling Contractors (N AHPCC) third party consultant No Group Nationwide TV & Appliance third pary consultant No Group Natural Gas Supply Association third party consultant No Group North Atlantic Energy Advisors third party consultant No Group Northern Power Systems third party consultant No Group 156 Table 3.5 (cont’d) OBAcorp third party consultant No Grog) ON Semiconductor third party consultant No Group PAH Associates third party consultant No Group Palo Alto Research Center (PARC) third party consultant No Grgp Peregrine Energy Group third party consultant No Group PlumbLng Manufacturers Institute third party consultant No Group Polyisocyanurate Insulation Manufacturers Association (PIMA) third party consultant No Group PositivEnergL third party consultant No Group Power Efficiency Corporation third party consultant No Group Power Integrations third party consultant No Group Predicate Energy, LLC third party consultant No Group Primen third party consultant No Group Public Solutions third party consultant No Group Pumps & Systems Magazine third party consultant No Group PWP, Inc. third party consultant No Group R. M. Shoemaker Construction third party consultant No Group R.L. Martin & Associates, Inc. third party consultant No Group RAND Corporation third party consultant No Group Real Estate Technologies Group third party consultant No Group RealWinWin, Inc. third party consultant No Group Resource Engineering Group, Inc. third party consultant No Group Richardson & Associates third pagty consultant No Group Ridge & Associates third party consultant No Group Rockwell Automation third party consultant No Group Rockwood International AS third party consultant No Group Ruhnke Consulting, Inc. third party consultant No Group Sanyo third party consultant No Group Sawtooth RM Woodcraft third party consultant No Group Schott Applied Power Corp third party consultant No Group SHADE Consulting, LLC third party consultant No Group Shockman Consulting third party consultant No Group Sieben EnergyAssociates third party consultant No Group Mark International third party consultant No Group Smart Systems International third party consultant No Group Solar Alternatives third party consultant No Cry Southwall Technologies third party consultant No Grog) Stellar Processes, Inc. third pargy consultant No Group Sunoptics Prismatic Skylights third party consultant No Group Superior Coils third party consultant No Group Sustainable Earth Enterprises third party consultant No Group 157 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Synertech Systems Corporation third party consultant No Group Systel-USA third party consultant No Group Takagi Industrial Co., Inc. third party consultant No Group Take Note Company third party consultant No Group Technical Consumer Products (TCP), Inc. third party consultant No Group Technology Prospects, Inc. third party consultant No Group Therrnalex, Inc. third party consultant No Group Thomsjo Services third party consultant No Group Two GatewayCenter third party consultant No Group U.S. Combined Heat & Power Association third party consultant No Group Unleash Inc. third party consultant No Group USAA Realty third party consultant No Group Veazey, Parrott, Durkin & Shoulders third party consultant No Group Venstar, Inc. third party consultant No Group Verified TM, Inc. third party consultant No Group Watt Stopper, Inc. third party consultant No Group Weatherwise USA Inc. third party consultant No Group West Hill Energy & Computing, Inc. third party consultant No OHM Westlab third party consultant No Group White-Rodgers third party consultant No Group ZGF Partnership third party consultant No Group American Electric Power Service Corp. utility No Group Association of Metropolitan Water Agencies utility No Group Atlantic City Electric Company utility No Group Aton Teknikkonsult AB utility No Group Baldor Electric Company utility No Group Bay State Gas utility No Group Berkshire Gas Company utility No Group Blacksburg, Christiansburg, VPI Water Authority utility No Group Central Vermont Public Service Comration utility No Group Cinergy Co. utility No Group Colorado Springs Utilities utility No Group Columbia Gas of Ohio, Inc. utility No Group Commonwealth Edison Company utility No Grog) Exelon Corporation utility No Group Florida Power Corporation utility No Group Gaz Metropolitain utility No Group Great River Energy utility No Group Idaho Power Company utility No Group Madison Gas & Electric Company utility No Group 158 Table 3.5 (cont’d) Narrpggnsett Electric utilifi No Group Reliant Enegy HL&P utility No Group Sempra Energy Utilities utility No Group Silicon ValleJLPower-City of Santa Clara utility No Group Southern Company Services, Inc. utility No Group Southern Minnesota Municipal Power Agency (SMMPA) utility No Gropp Tacoma City Light utility No Group Union Gas Limited utility No Group Utilicorp United Inc. utility No Group 159 Table 3.6: Cohesive Subgroup Organizational and Event Membership for 2001- 2006. ORGANIZATIONAL ORGANIZATION TYPE SUBGROUP Building Performance Institute, Inc. (BPI) eIEgy efficiency advocates 1 California Urban Water Conservation Council energy efficiency advocates 1 Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers (AHAM) regulated manufacturer 1 BSH Home Appliances flated manufacturer 1 Electrolux Inc. Wed manufacturer 1 Fisher & Paykel rgglated manufacturer 1 General Electric Consumer Products regplated manufacturer 1 Maytag Corporation regulated manufacturer I Whirlpool Corporation lpgulated manufacturer 1 Air Conditioning Contractors of America third party consultant I National Energy Management Institute third party consultant 1 Procter & Gamble third party consultant 1 Sears, Roebuck & Company third party consultant 1 Alliant Energy Corporation utility 1 Austin Water Utility utility I MidAmerican Energy Company utility 1 2002/7/18 ESRRFWS Energy Star Workshop 1 2004/10/6 ESCACWS Enegy Star Workshop 1 2004/8/15 ESCWWS Energy Star Workshop 1 2005/7/13 ESDWWS Enfly Star Workshop 1 Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (F ERC) federaljovernment 2 National Institutes of Standards and Technolfly (N 1ST) federal government 2 American Association of Retired Persons, Consumer Issues energy efficiency advocate 2 Appliance Standards Awareness Project (ASAP) eggy efficiency advocate 2 Center for Energy & Environment enggy efficiency advocate 2 Consumer Federation of America energy efficiency advocate 2 Northwest Power PlanningCouncil energy efficiency advocate 2 City of Austin regional goyemment 2 Air Conditioning & Refrigeration Institute (ARI) Egulated manufacturer 2 Allied Siflal, Inc. regulated manufacturer 2 ArmstrongyAir Conditionirg Inc. regulated manufacturer 2 Bard ManufacttLing Co. rflrted manufacturer 2 Carrier Corporation/United Technologips regLated manufacturer 2 160 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Copeland Corporation regulated manufacturer ECR International, Inc. rpgulated manufacturer Gas Appliance Manufacturers Association regulated manufacturer Goodman Manufacturing Company, LP. regulated manufacturer Hydrotherm Corporation, A Mestek Inc. regulated manufacturer International Comfort Products Corporation regulated manufacturer Lennox International Inc. regulated manufacturer Modine Manufacturirg Company regulated manufacturer Nordyne Co. regulated manufacturer Rheem Manufacturing Company regulated manufacturer Trane Company/American Standard regulated manufacturer Unico System regulated manufacturer York International Corporation regulated manufacturer NNNNNNNNNNNNNNNNNNNNN Energy Design Update third party consultant GPU Service Co. third party consultant Intertek Testifl Services third party consultant Systematic Mggement Services, Inc. third party consultant Wiley, Rein, & Fieldirg third party consultant Baltimore Gas & Electric utility Edison Electric Institute (EEI) utility Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI) utility National Rural Electric Cooperative Association utility 2 Pepco Holdings, Inc. utility 2 Virflia Power utility 2 2001/lO/2CACRMWS DOE Rulemakingl-Iearin 2 2001/3/29CACTPWS DOE RulemakingHearEg 2 Brooks Ermy & Sustainability Laboratory academic 3 California Lighting Techrmgy Center academic 3 California State University academic 3 Cwnpgie Mellon University academic 3 Oberlin College academic 3 Portland State University academic 3 Princeton University academic 3 Purdue University academic 3 Texas A&M University academic 3 University of California academic 3 University of Colorado academic 3 University of Washington academic 3 WasMon State Universitg academic 3 161 Table 3.6 (cont’d) National Aeronautics and Space Center federal government U.S. Congrgess federal government U.S. Department of Energy (U.S. DOE) federflovemment U.S. Department of Housing & Urban Development (HUD) federalgovemment 3 Australian Greenhouse Office international 3 BRANZ Ltd. international 3 Center for Energy Efficiency - EnEffect international 3 Central European University international 3 Central Research Institute of Electric Power Industry (CRIEPI) international 3 Central Research Institute of Electric Power Industry (CRIEPI), Japan international 3 Chalmers University of Technology, Sweden international 3 China Ceritifcation Center for Energy Conservation Product (CECP) international 3 China National Institute of Standardization international 3 Danish Building Research Institute international 3 Danish Energy Management A/S international 3 Energy Efficient Strategies, Australia international 3 Enova SF international 3 European Commission Directorate international 3 EVO international 3 Hydro Quebec international 3 Jyunkankyo Research Institute, Tokyo international 3 LinkopingUniversity international 3 Manitoba Hydro international 3 Ministry of Construction, China international 3 National Research Council Canada international 3 Natural Resources Canada international 3 NOVEM international 3 Osaka Gas international 3 Osaka University international 3 Regulatory Authority for Electricity & Gas, Italy international 3 United Nations international 3 University of Toronto international Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (LBNL) national lab 3 National Renewable Energy Laboratory (National Renewable Enfly Laboratory) national lab 3 Oak Ridge National Laboratory (ORNL) national lab 3 Pacific Northwest National Laboratory national lab 3 Academy for Educational Development (AED) energy efficiency advocate 3 162 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Academy for Educational Development (AED) engggefficiency advocate 3 Advanced EnergyCorporation energy efficiency advocate 3 Advanced Eneygy Corporation energy efficiency advocate 3 Affordable Comfort, Inc. (ACI) energy efficiency advocate 3 Association for Energy Affordability, Inc. (AEA) energy efficiency advocate Building Codes Assistance Project (BCAP) energy efficiency advocate California Climate Action Registry energy efficiency advocate California Home Energy Efficiency Rating System energy efficiency advocate 3 California Institute for Energy Efficiency CIEE) energy efficiency advocate Center for Neighborhood Technology (CNT) enfly efficiencgadvocate Clean Air - Cool Planet energy efficiency advocate Collaborative Labelling and Appliance Standards Program (CLASP) energy efficiency advocate 3 Community Enhancement Services energy efficiency advocate 3 Ecology Action energy efficiency advocate 3 Efficient Windows Collaborative energLefficiency advocate 3 Electric Solar Utility Network (ElectricSUN) energy efficiency advocate 3 Electricity Innovation Institute energy efficiengy advocate 3 Energy Center of Wisconsin (ECW) energy efficiency advocate 3 Energy Conservation Finance Institute (ECFI) energy efficiency advocate 3 Energy Foundation energy efficiency advocate 3 Energy Trust of Oregon (ETO) energy efficiency advocate 3 Florida Solar Energy Center energy efficiency advocate 3 Global Environment & Technology Foundation energy efficiency advocate Institute for Market Transformation energy efficiency advocate International Energy Agency (IEA) energy efficiency advocate International Institute for Energy Conservation (IIEC) energy efficiency advocate 3 International Institute for Energy Conservation (IIEC) energyefficiency advocate 3 Iowa Energy Center energy efficiency advocate 3 Lighting Research Center, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute (LRC) energy efficiency advocate Lower Colorado River Authority (LCRA) energy efficiency advocate Natural Resources Defense Council (N RDC) energy efficiency advocate Northeast States for Coordinated Air Use Management (N ESCAUM) energy efficiency advocate Northwest Power & Conservation Council energy efficiency advocate Pacific Institute energy efficiency advocate 163 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Pew Charitable Trusts enegy efficiency advocate Portland Enfly Conservation, Inc. (PECI) energyefficiency advocate Regulatory Assistance Project (RAP) engerggefficiency advocate Residential Energy Services Network (RESNET) energLefficiency advocate 3 Sierra Club energLefficiency advocate 3 Southern Alliance for Clean Energy enjgy efficiency advocate 3 Southwest Energy Efficiency Partnerships (SWEEP) enggy efficiency advocate 3 U.S. Green Building Council (USGBC) energmfficiency advocate 3 U.S. Green Building Council (USGBC) energy efficiency advocate 3 Bonneville Power Administration (BPA) regional government 3 California Energy Commission (CEC) regional government 3 California Public Utility Commission regional government 3 City of Boulder Egional government 3 City of Lompoc regional government 3 City of San Francisco regional government 3 City of Santa Monica regional government 3 New Jersey Board of Public Utilities regional gvemment 3 Ohio Office of Consumers' Council regional government 3 Oregon Office of Energy regional government 3 Vermont Department of Public Service rpgfional government 3 Western Area Power Administration (WAPA) regional government 3 Wisconsin Energy Bureau gional ggv'emment 3 Alternative Energy Systems Consultinflc. third party consultant 3 Appliance Recycling Centers of America, Inc. (ARCA) third party consultant 3 Architectural Enefiy Co. (ABC) third party consultant 3 Amp third party consultant 3 ASW Engineering third party consultant 3 Better Buildings Interactive third party consultant 3 Bevilacqua-Knight, Inc. third party consultant 3 Building Science Corporation third party consultant 3 Cardinal IG third party consultant 3 CH2M Hill third party consultant 3 CMC Energy Services third party consultant 3 Consol, Inc. third party consultant 3 Davis Energy Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 Demand Research third party consultant 3 Dethman & Associates third party consultant 3 Dunlap & Browder, Inc. third party consultant 3 Dunsky Energy Consulting third party consultant 3 164 Table 3.6 (cont’d) DuPont third party consultant 3 Duro-Last Roofing, Inc. third party consultant 3 ECONorthwest third party consultant 3 Ecos Consultifll Inc. thirdJarty consultant 3 Ecotope, Inc. third party consultant 3 Eley Associates third party consultant 3 Energy & Resource Solutions, Inc. third party consultant 3 Energy Conservatory third party consultant 3 Energy Market Innovations, Inc. third party consultant 3 Ermy Solutions Unltd. third party consultant 3 EnVinta Corp. third party consultant 3 Equipoise Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 E-SOURCE/Platts third party consultant 3 Etc. Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 Franklin Energy Services, Inc. third party consultant 3 Freeman & Associates, LLC third party consultant 3 Freeman, Sullivan & Co. thirdJartyconsultant 3 Frontier Associates third party consultant 3 Geltz Communications third party consultant 3 GeoPraxis, Inc. third party consultant 3 Gruenreich Resource Advocates third party consultant 3 H. Gil Peach & Associates LLC third party consultant 3 Heschong Mahone Group, Inc. third party consultant 3 HMW International, Inc. third party consultant 3 Home Building Technology Services third party consultant 3 Home Energy Magazine third party consultant 3 IBACOS, Inc. third party consultant 3 Ice Energy LLC third party consultant 3 Innovologie, LLC third party consultant 3 Invensys third partyconsultant 3 Itron, Inc. third party consultant 3 KEMA, Inc. third party consultant 3 KEMA-XENERGY, Inc. third party consultant 3 KJ Consulting third party consultant 3 kW Engineering third party consultant 3 Loisos & Ubbelohde Associates third party consultant 3 Megdal & Associates third party consultant 3 Morfl Marketing Partners, LLC third party consultant 3 Navigant Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 I65 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Nexant, Inc. third party consultant 3 North American Insulation Manufacturers Association (NAIMA) third party consultant 3 North American Technician Excellence third party consultant 3 Optimal Energy, Inc. third party consultant 3 Orion Energy Systems, Ltd. third party consultant 3 Owens CorLing third party consultant 3 PA ConsultigngGroup, Inc. third party consultant 3 Performance Systems Development, Inc. third party consultant 3 Peter Benenson Consulting third parjy consultant 3 Peter Schwartz & Associates third party consultant 3 Potomac Resources, Inc. third party consultant 3 Prahl & Associates third party consultant 3 Proctor Engineering Group, Ltd. third party consultant 3 Quantec, LLC third party consultant 3 Quantum Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Michal Economic Research, Inc. third party consultant 3 Research Into Action, Inc. third party consultant 3 Rita Norton & Associates, LLC third party consultant 3 RLW Analytics, Inc. third party consultant 3 Robert Mowris & Associates third party consultant 3 SBW Consulting, Inc. third party consultant 3 Schiller Associates third party consultant 3 Science Applications International Co. (SAICy third party consultant 3 She] Feldman Management Consultants third party consultant 3 Sheltersource, Inc. third party consultant 3 Skumatz Economic Research Associates, Inc. third party consultant 3 Steven Winter Associates, Inc. third party consultant 3 Strategic Energy Technoltgjes, Inc. third party consultant 3 Summit Blue ConsultiniILC third party consultant 3 Sustainable Energy Partnerships third party consultant 3 Synapse Energy Economics, Inc. third party consultant 3 TecMRKT Works LLC third party consultant 3 TIAX, LLC third party consultant 3 TRC Enegy Services third party consultant 3 Truveon Co. thirgparty consultant 3 Valley Energy Efficiency Co. third party consultant 3 Vermont Energy Investment Co. (VEIC) third party consultant 3 Vistron Corp. third papty consultant 3 Weidt Group third party consultant 3 Wirtshafter Associates, Inc. third party consultant 3 166 Table 3.6 (cont’dL Xenergy, Inc. third party consultant 3 Yinsight thiflartyconsultant 3 AQUILA utility 3 British Columbia Gas Utility Ltd. utility 3 British Columbia Hydro utility 3 Community Energy Cooperative utility 3 Enbridge Gas Distribution utility 3 Entergy utility 3 Egene Water & Electric Board utility 3 Nevada Power Company utility 3 Northwest Natural Gas Company utility 3 Oncor Energy utility 3 Pacific Gas & Electric Company utility 3 Portland General Electric Company utility 3 m Sound Energy LPSE) utility 3 Sacramento Municipal Utility District utility 3 Salt River Project (SRP) utility 3 San Dieg) Gas & Electric Co. (SDG&E) utility 3 Seattle City Light utility 3 Sierra Pacific Power Company utility 3 Southern California Edison Company (SCE) utiliy 3 Southern California Gas Company utility 3 Tacoma Power utility 3 TXU Electric Company utility 3 We Energies utility 3 Western Massachusetts Electric Co. utility 3 Xcel Energy, Inc. utility 3 2002 SS Summer Study Conference 3 2004 SS Summer StudyConference 3 2006 SS Summer Study Conference 3 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (U SEPA) federaljovemment 4 Alliance to Save Energy energy efficiency advocate 4 American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE) energy efficiency advocate 4 Consortium for Energy Efficiency, Inc. (CEE) energy efficiency advocate 4 Economic Opportunity Research Institute energy efficiency advocate 4 Efficiency Vermont energy efficiency advocate 4 Energy and Environmental Building Association (EEBA) energy efficiency advocate Energy Coordinating Agency of PA, Inc. energy efficiency advocate 167 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Energy Federation, Inc. Iggy efficiency advocate 4 Marketing Science Institute energmfficiency advocate 4 Midwest Energy Efficiency Alliance (MEEA) energy efficiency advocate 4 National Albanian American Council energy efficiency advocate 4 National Center for Energy Management and Building Technologies (NCEMBT) energy efficiency advocate 4 National Ermy Foundation energy efficiency advocate 4 Natural Resources Council of Maine eggy efficiency advocate 4 New Buildings Institute, Inc. (N BI) enggy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Energy Efficiency Council eflgy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Energy Efficiency Partnerships, Inc. energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Midwest Institute energy efficiency advocate 4 Northeast Power Planning Council energy efficiency advocate 4 Northwest EnegyEtficiency Alliance (N EEA) energyefficiency advocate 4 Northwest Energy Efficiency Council energy efficiency advocate 4 Rocky Mountain Institute (RMI) energy efficiency advocate 4 Technical Development Corporation energy efficiency advocate 4 Vermont Energy Investment Corporation energy efficiency advocate 4 Wisconsin Energy Conservation Corporation/ Focus on Energy energy efficiency advocate 4 District of Columbia Public Service Commission regional government 4 Idaho Public Utilities Commission re ional government 4 Maine Public Utilities Commission rgional @vemment 4 Maryland Enggy Administration regional government 4 Massachusetts Division of Energy Resources regional government 4 New York State Energy Research & Development Authority (N YSERDA) regional @vemment 4 Ohio Department of Development regional government 4 Ohio Office of Energy Efficiency Legional ggvemment 4 Effikal International, Inc. regulated manufacturer 4 F lowserve Corp. Eulated manufacturer ‘ 4 Good Earth Lighiipg re lated manufacturer 4 Honeywell, Inc. re lated manufacturer 4 Applied Proactive Technology, Inc. (APT) third party consultant 4 Aspen Systems Co. third party consultant 4 Cadmus Group, Inc. third party consultant 4 Conservation Services Group, Inc. (CSG) third party consultant 4 Copper Development Association Inc. third party consultant 4 D & R International Ltd. third party consultant 4 EAM Associates, Inc. third party consultant 4 ERG International, Inc. third party consultant 4 168 Table 3.6 (cont’d) GDS Associates, Inc. third party consultant 4 _Hpggman Inc. third party consultant 4 Hydraulic Institute third party consultant 4 ICF Consultingglnc. third party consultant 4 ITT Industrial Products Corp. third party consultant 4 LDL Consulting third party consultant 4 Lockheed Martin Aspen Systems third party consultant 4 Magrann Associates third party consultant 4 Marlflg Drive Worldwide third party consultant 4 MCN third party consultant 4 National Association of Energy Service Companies (NAESCO) third party consultant 4 National Electrical Manufacturers Association (N EMA) third party consultant 4 Nexus Energglnc. third party consultant 4 North American Retail Dealers Association (NARDA) third party consultant 4 Northeast by Northwest third party consultant 4 Opinion Dynamics Corporation third party consultant 4 Pacific EnergLAssociates, Inc. third party consultant 4 PRR third party consultant 4 Resource Planning Group third party consultant 4 Schleil& Associates third party consultant 4 SENTECH, Inc. third party consultant 4 Servidyne Systems, LLC third party consultant 4 TraynorKirk and Co. third party consultant 4 Wisconsin Energy Conservation third party consultant 4 Austin Energy utility 4 Center Point Energy utility 4 Conectiv Power Delivery utility 4 Georgia Power Co. utility 4 Jersey Central Power & Lim utility 4 Keyspan Energy Corp. utility 4 Lonflland Power Authority (LIPA) utility 4 National Grid USA utility 4 New Hampshire Electric Cooperative, Inc. utility 4 Northeast Utilities utility 4 NSTAR Electric & Gas utility 4 Public Service Electric & Gas Company utility 4 South Jersey Gas Company utility 4 United Illuminatifi Co. utility 4 Vermont Gas Systems, Inc. utility 4 169 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Market Transformation 2001MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2002MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2003MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2004MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2005MT Symposium 4 Market Transformation 2006MT Symposium 4 American Association for the Advancement of Science (AAAS) academic No Group City University of New York (CUNY) academic No Group Cornell University academic No Group Daylighting Lab academic No Group GeorggMason University academic No Group Green Mountain College academic No Group Hong-Ik University academic No Group Howard University academic No Group Kansas State University academic No Group Michigan State University academic No Group National Center for Atmospheric Research (N CAR) academic No Group Oregon Renewable Energy Center academic No Group Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute academic No Group Umea University academic No Group University of Alaska academic No Group University of Delaware academic No Group University of Idaho academic No Group University of Illinois academic No Group University of Maryland academic No Group University of Michigan academic No Group University of Nevada academic No Group University of North Carolina academic No Group Vermont Law School academic No Group U.S.Agency for International Development federal government No Group U.S. Department of Agriculture (DOA) federal government No Group U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) federa_lgovemment No Group U.S. General Services Administration federal wemment No Grog) _Agencia Nacional de Enlflyia Electrica international No Group Beijing Association of Sustainable Development international No Group 170 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Beijing Electric Light Sources Research Institute international No Group Befiing Enegy Efficiency Center international No Group Berliner Energie_agentur Ltd. international No Group _Big Switch Projects international No Group Butwal Power Company P. Ltd. international No Group Carbon Trust international No Group Centre for Renewable Energy Systems Technology international No Group Cete de Lyon international No Group CFL Harmonisation Initiative international No Group China Sustainable Energy Wm international No Group Commergy Ltd. international No Group Danish Electricity Saving Trust Fund international No Group Danish Energy Agency international No Group Dutch Ministg of Economic Affairs international No Group E.V.A. the Austrian Energy Agency international No Group Ecole des Mines de Paris international No Group Econoler International international No Group Efficiency NB international No Group Eletrobras/Procel international No Group Energy Efficiency and Conservation Authority international No Group Energy Research Institute, China international No Group Exergy Australia Pty Ltd international No Group Golden Power Manufacturingind. international No Group Government of Canada international No Group Housing & Building Research Center (HBRC), _Egypt international No Group [E] international No Group IFZ - Inter-University Research Center international No Group IIEU international No Groug Industrial Technology Research Institute (ITRI) international No Group Institut fur Energie und Umweltforschung international No Group Institute of Local Government Studies (AKFL international No Group Instituto de Investigaciones Electricas international No Group Joint Research Centre of the European Communities international No Group Kerma, Inc. international No Group Korea Gas Co.. international No Group Korea Institute of Energy Research (KIER) international No Group Kyushu University, Japan international No Group LivingWise international No Group 17] Table 3.6 (cont’d) Mexican Energy Saving National Commission CONAE international No Group Mid Sweden University international No Group National Development & Reform Commission, China international No Group NCC Nordic Construction Company international No Group Ontario Power Technologies international No Group PROCEL/Eletrobras international No Group Royal Nepal Academy of Science and Tech. international No Group Saskatchewan Research Council international No Group Shanghai Energy Conservation Supervision Center international No Group Shanghai HousigngDevelopment Bureau international No Group Sietten Finnmark AS international No Group State Economic & Trade Commission international No Group Surya Roshni international No Group Technical University of Denmark international No Group Terasen Gas international No Group Tokyo University international No Group Trilogy Holdings, Ltd. international No Group UK. Market Transformation Program international No Group _Uganda Christian University Mukono international No Group University of British Columbia international No Group University of Kassel international No Group University of New South Wales international No Group University of Twente international No Group University of Waterloo international No Group Victoria University of Wellington international No Group Brookhaven National Laboratory national lab No Group Idaho National Engineering & Environment Laboratory national lab No Group Electric Solar Utility Network (ElectricSUN) energy efficiency advocate No Group Environmental & Energy Study Institute academic No Group eProcurement Project flgy efficiency advocate No Group Focus on Energy energgefficiency advocate No Group Four Winds Resource and Conservation Area energy efficiency advocate No Group International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives (ICLEI) energy efficiency advocate No Grog) Kentucky Pollution Prevention Center energy efficiency advocate No Group National Commission on EnegLPolicy energy efficiency advocate No Group Northeast Premium Efficiency Motor Initiative energy efficiency advocate No Group PATH energy efficiency advocate No Group Vermont Campus Energy Group em efficiency advocate No Group 172 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Virgfl Housifi& Environment Network enfiy efficiency advocate No Group WestEd energy efficiency advocate No Group Arkansas State Enegy Office regional government No Group Avondale regional government No Group California Department of General Administration lpgionaljovemment No Group Champlain Valley Office of Economic Opportunity (CVOEO) regional government No Group City of Berkeley rggional government No Group City of Oakland regional government No Group City of Palo Alto regional government No Group City of Pleasanton regional government No Group City of San Jose rpgional government No Group City of Seattle regional government No Group City of Springfield regionfiovemment No Group Georgia Environmental Facilities Authority regional government No Group Idaho Department of Resources Egional government No Group Indiana Consumer Advocate Office regional government No Group Inland Empire Utilities Agency regional government No Group Iowa Department of Justice, Office of Consumer Advocate regional government No Group Kentucky Office of Energy Policy regional government No Group Louisville Metro Air Pollution Control District regional government No Group Maine State Planning Office regional government No Group Massachusetts Board of Building£gulations regional government No Group Missouri Energy Center re ional government No Group Moorhead Public Service Department Eional government No Group National Association of State Energy Offices regional government No Group New Hampshire Public Utilities Commission re ional government No Group North Carolina Department of Commerce regional government No Group Public Service Commission of Wisconsin regional government No Group San Dieg) County Water Authority regional government No Group San Diego Regional Energy Office regional government No Group San Francisco Public Utilities Commission regional government No Group Seattle Public Utilities pegional government No Group Snohomish County Public Utilities Commission Egional government No Grog) Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) regional government No Group Utah Energy Office rggional government No Group A.O. Smith Co. refllaIed manufacturer No Group Absocold rpgulated manufacturer No Group Advanced Conservation Technologies, Inc. (ACT) Metlund Systems regulated manufacturer No Group 173 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Amana Refrigeration Inc. regulated manufacturer No Group American Fluorescent Egulated manufacturer No Group Climate Master regulated manufacturer No Group Emerson Motor Co regulated manufacturer No Group Flanders Electric of IL regulated manufacturer No Group Goulds Pumps - ITT Industries regylated manufacturer No Group Haier Egulated manufacturer No Group Marcelo regulated manufacturer No Group Marvel Industries regulated manufacturer No Group Microfridge regulated manufacturer No Group Miele regulated manufacturer No Group National Comfort Products regrlated manufacturer No Group Philips Lighting Co. regulated manufacturer No Group Samsung Air Conditioners re lated manufacturer No Group Space Pak regulated manufacturer No Group Staber Industries regulated manufacturer No Group Sun Frost regulated manufacturer No Group U-Line Corporation regulated manufacturer No Group Ultra 8 International / Ariston Appliances rewed manufacturer No Group United Technologies Research Center regulated manufacturer No Group W. C. Wood Company Limited regulated manufacturer No Group ADM Associates, Inc. third party consultant No Group Aeroseal third party consultant No Group Afterimage + Space third party consultant No Group Air Conditioning, Heating & Refrigeration News third party consultant No Group Alewife EnergL& Environment third party consultant No Group All Star Construction third party consultant No Group American Gas Association (AGA) third party consultant No Group American Lighting Association (ALA) third party consultant No Group American Synergy Co. third party consultant No Group Applied Energy Research Group third pagI consultant No Group Applied Engineering Management third pargl consultant No Group Applied Flow Technology third party consultant No Group Applied Innovations Research third party consultant No Group Applied Resources Group third paptyconsultant No Group Arthur D. Little, Inc.(ADL) third party consultant No Group Association of Energy Service Professionals (AESP) third party consultant No Group ATOF INA Chemicals, Inc. third party consultant No Group Ayala Land Inc/Ayala Property Mgt. Corp. third party consultant No Group 174 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Benya Lighting Design third party consultant No Group Berkeley Solar Group third party consultant No Group Bozell Kamstra third party consultant No Group Braebum Systems third party consultant No Group Bramante Energy, Inc. third party consultant No Group Brand Source - AVB third party consultant No Group Buderus Hydronic Systems third party consultant No Group Business & Energy Services third party consultant No Group Calyx Investments third party consultant No Group Caneta Research, Inc. third party consultant No Group Cannon Technologies third party consultant No Group Chitwood Energy Manament third party consultant No Group Chog Partners Architecture third party consultant No Group Chris Robertson & Associates, LLC third party consultant No Group CLEAResult Consultin , Inc. third pary consultant No Group Climate Energy, LLC third party consultant No Group Comfort Diagnostics & Solutions third party consultant No Group Competitive Resources, Inc. third party consultant No Group Concurrent Technologies Corp. third party consultant No Group Consumer Powerline third party consultant No Group Costco third party consultant No Group CS&M Marketing third party consultant No Group CT C third party consultant No Group Curtiss-Wright EMD third party consultant No Grog) Dawnbreaker third party consultant No Group Design AVEnues third party consultant No Group Eastern Research Group third party consultant No Group Ed Malemezian Consulting, Inc. third party consultant No Group Electrical Apparatus Service Association third party consultant No Group Electronic Industries Alliance third party consultant No Group Elemental Enterprises third party consultant No Group Elf Atochem North America, Inc. third party consultant No Group Enercomp, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energetics, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy & Environmental Management ngazine third party consultant No Group Energy and Environmental Economics, Inc. third papty consultant No Group Energy Economics, Inc. third party consultant No Group Eneggy Market & Policy Analysis, Inc. third party consultant No Group Energy Saving Products, Ltd. third party consultant No Group I75 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Envenergy third party consultant No Group Environmental Interface, Ltd. third party consultant No Group Esherick Homsey Dodge & Davis third party consultant No Grog; ETW Inc. third party consultant No Group F. Smothers & Associates third party consultant No Group First Tracks Consultlg Service, Inc. third party consultant No Group Florida Home Energy & Resources _O_rganization (HEROL third party consultant No Group Flowcare Eflineering Inc. third party consultant NO Group Frito-Lay third party consultant No Group GH Consulting, LLC third parg consultant No Group Global Energy Options third party consultant No Group Global Energy Partners, LLC third party consultant No Group Green Homes America third party consultant No Group Green Order third party consultant No Group Grimason Associates, LLC third party consultant No Group Gunnar Hovstadius Consumg, L.L.C. third party consultant No Group Habart & Associates Consulting Inc. third party consultant No Group Halton Company third party consultant No Group Harris Design Inc. third party consultant No Group Hatch Consulting third party consultant No Group HEC, Inc. third party consultant No Group Hill and Knowlton third party consultant No Group Hoffman Corporation third party consultant No Group Hoffman LLCNertegy third party consultant No Group Hoffman York third party consultant No Group Home Depot third party consultant No Group Home Excellence, Inc. third party consultant No Group HPAC Engineering third party consultant No Group lcynene Co. third party consultant No Group Innovest Strategic Value Advisors third party consultant No Group INSIGHT third party consultant No Group Insights Unlimited third party consultant No Group Integrated Design Associates, Inc. third party consultant No Group Interbrand third party consultant No Group J. Ottman Consulting third party consultant No Group Jaco Environmental third party consultant No Group Jim Perich-Anderson Consulting third party consultant No Group John Manville third party consultant No Group KAT Consultii third party consultant No Group KER] third party consultant No Group 176 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Lambert Engfleeringlnc. third party consultant No Group Les Tumidaj & Associates third party consultant No Group Levy Associates third party consultant No Group Lighting Wizards third party consultant No Group LumenX, Inc. third party consultant No Group Lutron Electronics Co., Inc. third party consultant No Group MaxLite third party consultant No Group Mintz, Levin, Cohn, Ferris, Glovsky and Popeo, P.C third party consultant No Group Mitsubishi Electronics America, Inc. third party consultant No Group MSI Consulting third party consultant No Group Mullen Advertising third party consultant No Group National Association of Home Builders (N AI-IB) third party consultant No Group National Association of Plumbing Heating Cooling Contractors (N AHPCC) third party consultant No Group Nationwide TV & Appliance third party consultant No Group Natural Gas Supply Association third party consultant No Group North Atlantic Energy Advisors third party consultant No Group Northern Power Systems third party consultant No Group OBAcorp third party consultant No Group ON Semiconductor third party consultant No Group PAH Associates third party consultant No Group Palo Alto Research Center (PARC) third party consultant No Group Peregrine Energy Group third party consultant No Group Plumbirg Manufacturers Institute third party consultant No Group Polyisocyanurate Insulation Manufacturers Association Q’IMA) third party consultant No Group PositivEnergy third party consultant No Group Power Efficiency Corporation third party consultant No Group Power Integrations third party consultant No Group Predicate Energy, LLC third party consultant No Group Primen third party consultant No Group Public Solutions third party consultant No Grog: Pumps & Systems Magazine third party consultant No Group PWP, Inc. third party consultant No Group R. M. Shoemaker Construction third party consultant No Group R.L. Martin & Associates, Inc. third party consultant No Group RAND Corporation third party consultant No Group Real Estate Technologies Group third party consultant No Group RealWinWin, Inc. third party consultant No Group Resource Engineering Group, Inc. third party consultant No Group I77 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Ridge & Associates third party consultant No Group Rockwell Automation third party consultant No Group Rockwood International AS third party consultant No Group Ruhnke ConsultinLInc. third party consultant No Group Sanyo third party consultant No Group Sawtooth Ridge Woodcraft third party consultant No Group Schott Applied Power Corp third party consultant NO Group SHADE Consulting, LLC third party consultant No Group Shockman Consulting third party consultant No Group Sieben Energy Associates third party consultant No Grorm Skymark International third party consultant No Group Smart Systems International third party consultant No Group Solar Alternatives third party consultant No Group Southwall Technolofis third party consultant No Group Stellar Processes, Inc. third party consultant No Group Sunoptics Prismatic Skylights third party consultant No Group Superior Coils third party consultant No Group Sustainable Earth Enterprises third party consultant No Group Synertech Systems Corporation third party consultant No Group Systel-USA third party consultant No Group Takagi Industrial Co., Inc. third party consultant No Group Take Note Company third party consultant No Group Technical Consumer Products (TCP), Inc. third party consultant No Group Technology Prospects, Inc. third party consultant No Group Therrnalex, Inc. third party consultant No Group Thomsjo Services third party consultant No Group Two Gateway Center third party consultant NO Group U.S. Combined Heat & Power Association third party consultant No Group Unleash Inc. third party consultant No Group USAA Realty third paprtyconsultant No Group Veazey, Parrott, Durkin & Shoulders third party consultant No Group Venstar, Inc. third party consultant No Group Verified TM, Inc. third party consultant No Group Watt Stopper, Inc. third pargl consultant No Group Weatherwise USA Inc. third party consultant No Group West Hill Energy & Computing, Inc. third party consultant No Group Westlab third party consultant No Group White-Rodgers third party consultant No Group ZGF Partnership third party consultant No Group 178 Table 3.6 (cont’d) Atlantic City Electric Company utility No Group Aton Teknikkonsult AB utility No Group Baldor Electric Company utility No Group Bay State Gas utility No Group Berkshire Gas Company utility No Group Blacksburg, Christiansburg VPI Water Auth. utility No Group Central Vermont Public Service Corporation utility No Group Cinergy Co. utility No Group Colorado Springs Utilities utility No Group Columbia Gas of Ohio, Inc. utility No Group Commonwealth Edison Company utility No Group Exelon Corporation utility No Group Florida Power Corporation utility No Group Gaz Metropolitain utility No Group Great River Energy utility No Group Idaho Power Company utility No Group Madison Gas & Electric Company utility No Group Narrpgansett Electric utility No Group Reliant Energy HL&P utility No Group Sempra Energy Utilities utility No Group Silicon Valley Power-City of Santa Clara utility No Group Southern Company Services, Inc. utility No Group Southern Minnesota Municipal Power Agency utility No Group Tacoma City Light utility No Group Union Gas Limited utility No Group Utilicorp United Inc. utility No Group 179 LITERATURE CITED 180 LITERATURE CITED 1985. "Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. v. Herrington, 768 F .2d 1355." United States Court Of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit. Alley, R., T. Bemtsen, N. Bindoff, Z. Chen, A. Chidthaisong, and P. Friedlingstein. 2007. "IPCC, 2007: Summary for policymakers." Climate Changez2—l8. Amenta, E. 2005. "State-Centered and Political Institutional Theory: Retrospect and Prospect] ." The Handbook of Political Sociology: States, Civil Societies, and Globalization. Andrews, K. T. and B. Edwards. 2005. "The Organizational Structure of Local Environmentalism." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 10:21 3-234. Andrews, R. N. L. 2006. Managing the Environment, Managing Ourselves: A History of American Environmental Policy: Yale University Press. Aupperle, K. E., A. B. Carroll, and J. D. Hatfield. 1985. "An empirical examination Of the relationship between corporate social responsibility and profitability." Academy of Management Journal 28:446-463. Bansal, P. 2003. "From Issues to Actions: The importance of individual concerns and organizational values." Organization Science 14:510-526. Bansal, P. and I. Clelland. 2004. "Talking Trash: Legitimacy, Impression Management, and Unsystematic Risk in the Context of the Natural Environment." Academy of Management Journal 47:93-104. Bansal, P. and J. Gao. 2006. "Building the Future by Looking to the Past: Examining Research Published on Organizations and Environment." Organization & Environment 19:458. Bansal, P. and K. Roth. 2000. "Why Companies Go Green: A Model of Ecological Responsiveness." Academy of Management Journal 43:717-737. Baum, J. A. C. and C. Oliver. 1991. "Institutional Linkages and Organizational Mortality." Administrative Science Quarterly 36:187-218. Beamish, T. D. 2001. "Environmental Hazard and Institutional Betrayal: Lay-Public Perceptions Of Risk in the San Luis Obispo County Oil Spill." Organization & Environment 14:5. —. 2002. Silent Spill: The Organization of an Industrial Crisis: MIT Press. 181 Beck, U. 1992. Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity: Sage. Berenbaum, M. R. 1999. Our Common Journey: A Transition Toward Sustainability: National Academy Press. Breiger, R. L. 1974. "Duality of Persons and Groups, The." Social Forces 53:181. Brewer, G. D. and P. C. Stern. 2005. Decision Making for the Environment: Social and Behavioral Science Research Priorities: National Academy Press. Brint, S. and J. Karabel. 1991. "Institutional origins and transformations: The case of American community colleges." The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysisz337-360. Brown, R., C. Webber, and J. G. Koomey. 2002. "Status and future directions Of the Energy Star program." Energy 27:505-520. Brulle, R. J. 2000. Agency, Democracy, and Nature: The US Environmental Movement from a Critical Theory Perspective: MIT Press. Brulle, R. J. and J. C. Jenkins. 2005. "Foundations and the Environmental Movement: Priorities, Strategies, and Impact." Foundations for Social Change: Critical Perspectives on Philanthropy and Popular Movements: 15 1—73. —. 2006. "Spinning Our Way to Sustainability?" Organization & Environment 19:82. Burke, L. and J. M. Logsdon. 1996. "How corporate social responsibility pays off." Long Range Planning 29:495-502. Burns, T. R. and T. Dietz. 1992. "Cultural Evolution: Social Rule Systems, Selection and Human Agency." International Sociology 7:259. Buttel, F. H. 2002. "Environmental Sociology and the Sociology of Natural Resources: Institutional Histories and Intellectual Legacies." Society & Natural Resources 15:205-211. —. 2004. "The Treadmill of Production: An Appreciation, Assessment, and Agenda for Research." Organization & Environment 17:323. Buttel, F. H. and A. Gijswijt. 2000. "Emerging Trends in Environmental Sociology." Blackwell companion to sociology:43-57. California Energy Commission. 2005. "Compliance Options Approval Manual for the Building Energy Efficiency Standards." vol. CEC-400-2005-007. 182 Campbell, J. L. 2005. "Where do we stand? Common mechanisms in organizations and social movements research." Social Movements and Organization Theoryz41-68. Caniglia, B. S. 2001. "Informal Alliances vs. Institutional Ties: The Effects of Elite Alliances on Environmental TSMO Networks." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 6:37-54. Caniglia, B. S. and J. A. Carmin. 2005. "Scholarship on Social Movement Organziations: Classic Views and Emerging Trends." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 10:201-212. Carmin, J. and D. B. Balser. 2002. "Selecting Repertoires of Action in Environmental Movement Organizations: An Interpretive Approach." Organization & Environment 15:365. Catton, W. R. and R. E. Dunlap. 197 8. "Paradigms, theories, and the primacy of the HEP- NEP distinction." The American Sociologist 13:256-259. Clark, B. and R. York. 2005. "Carbon metabolism: Global capitalism, climate change, and the biospheric rift." Theory and Society 34:391-428. Clemens, E. S. 1997. The People 's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925: University Of Chicago Press. Clemens, E. S. and J. M. Cook. 1999. "Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining Durability and Change." Annual Reviews in Sociology 25:441-466. Cohen, M. J. 1998. "Science and the environment: Assessing cultural capacity for ecological modernization." Public Understanding of Science 7:149. —. 2006. "Ecological modernization and its discontents: The American environmental movement's resistance to an innovation-driven future." Futures 38:528-547. Cox, A., P. Furlong, and E. Page. 1985. Power in capitalist societies: theory, explanations and cases: Wheatsheaf Books. Dacin, M. T., J. Goodstein, and W. R. Scott. 2002. "Institutional Theory and Institutional Change: Introduction to the Special Research Forum." Academy of Management Journal 45:45-57. Dahl, R. A. 2005. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City: Yale University Press. deLeon, P. and Jorge E. Rivera. 2007. "Voluntary Environmental Programs: A Symposium." Policy Studies Journal 35:685-688. 183 Dietz, T. 2005. "The Darwinian trope in the drama of the commons: variations on some themes by the Ostroms." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 57:205-225. Dietz, T. and P. C. Stern. 2002. New Tools for Environmental Protection: Education, Information and Voluntary Measures. Washington, DC: National Academies Press. Dietz, T.and A.D. Henry. 2008. "Context and the commons." Proceedings of the National Academies of Science 205: 13189-13190. DiMaggio, P. J. and W. W. Powell. 1983. "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality." American Sociological Review 48: 147- 160. Dunlap, R. E. 1992. "Trends in Public Opinion Toward Environmental Issues: 1965- 1990." American Environmentalism: The US Environmental Movement, 1970- I 990 1 1 1 . Dunlap, R. E. and R. Scarce. 1991. "Poll Trends: Environmental Problems and Protection." Public Opinion Quarterly 55:651-672. Dutton, J. E., S. J. Ashford, R. M. O'Neill, B. Hayes, and E. E. Wierba. 1997. "Reading the wind: how middle managers assess the context for selling issues to top managers." Strategic Management Journal 18:407-423. Eckstein, R. 1997. Nuclear Power and Social Power. Philadelphia: Temple University Press. Energy Information Administration. 1985. "Annual Outlook for U.S. Electric Power 1985." —. 1992. "The Changing Structure of the U.S. Electric Power Industry 1970-1991." edited by U. S. D. 0. Energy. —. 2008. "Greenhouse Gases, Climate Change, and Energy." vol. DOE/EIA-X012, edited by U. S. D. 0. Energy: U.S. Government Printing Office. Environmental Protection Agency. 2008. "Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas and Sinks: 1990-2006." vol. USEPA #430-R-08-005, edited by U. S. E. P. Agency. Eto, J. 1996. "The past, present, and future of US utility demand-side management programs." LBNL--39931, Lawrence Berkeley National Lab., CA. Evans, P. B., D. Rueschemeyer, and T. Skocpol. 1985. Bringing the State Back In: Cambridge University Press. 184 Faust, K. 2005. "Using Correspondence Analysisfor Joint Displays ofAffiIiation Networks." Models and Methods in Social NetworkAnalysis. Field, 8., K. A. Frank, K. Schiller, C. Riegle-Crumb, and C. Muller. 2006. "Identifying positions from affiliation networks: Preserving the duality of people and events." Social Networks 28:97-123. Fineman, S. and K. Clarke. 1996. "Green Stakeholers: Industry interpretation and Response." Journal of Management Studies 33 :7 1 5-730. Finlay, J. 1999. Beyond Grey Pinstripes: Preparing MBAs for Social and Environmental Stewardship. Washington DC: World Resources Institute. Fisher, D. R. and W. R. Freudenburg. "Ecological Efficiency, Disproportionality and Methodological Precision: on the Importance of Linking Methods to Theory." —. 2001. "Ecological Modernization and Its Critics: Assessing the Past and Looking Toward the Future." Society & Natural Resources 14:701-709. Fligstein, N. 1991. "The Structural Transformation of American Industry: An Institutional Account of the Causes of Diversification in the Largest Firms, 1919- 1979." The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysisz311-336. Freudenburg, W. R. and P. Nowak. 2000. "Disproportionality and Disciplinary Blinders: Understanding the Tail that Wags the Dog." Galaskiewicz, J. and M. S. Colman. 2006. "Collaboration between Corporations and Nonprofit Organizations." The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook. Gardner, G. T. and P. C. Stern. 1995. Environmental problems and human behavior: Allyn and Bacon. Geller, H. and S. Nadel. 1994. "Market Transformation Strategies to Promote End-Use Efficiency." Annual Reviews in Energy and the Environment 19:301-346. Gillingham, K., R. Newell, and K. Palmer. 2006. "Energy Efficiency Policies: A Retrospective Examination." Annual Reviews in Energy and the Environment. Gladwin, T. N., J. J. Kennelly, and T. S. Krause. 1995. "Shifting Paradigms for Sustainable Development: Implications for Management Theory and Research." Academy of Management Review 20:874—907. Gore, A. 1993, "The Climate Change Action Plan", Retrieved October 10, 2008 (http://www.gcrio.org/USCCAP/index.html). 185 —. 2006. "An Inconvenient Truth. The Planetary Emergency of Global Warming and What We Can DO About It." New York. Gould, A. and K. A. Gould. 1994. "Environment and Society: The Enduring Conflict." New York: St. Martin’s Press. Gould, K. A., D. N. Pellow, and A. Schnaiberg. 2004. "Interrogating the Treadmill Of Production: Everything You Wanted to Know about the Treadmill but Were Afraid tO Ask." Organization & Environment 17:296. Grant, D. and A. W. Jones. 2003. "Are Subsidiaries More Prone to Pollute? New Evidence from the EPA's Toxics Release Inventory*." Social Science Quarterly 84: 162-173. Grant, D., A. W. Jones, and M. N. Trautner. 2004. "DO Facilities with Distant Headquarters Pollute More-How Civic Engagement Conditions the Environmental Performance of Absentee Managed Plants." Social Forces 83:189. Greenwood, R. and C. R. Hinings. 1996. "Understanding Radical Organizational Change: Bringing together the Old and new institutionalists." The Academy of Management review 21:1022-1054. Harman, M. T. and J. Freeman. 1977. "The Population Ecology of Organizations." American Journal of Sociology 82:929. Hays, S. P. 2000. A history of environmental politics since 1945: University Of Pittsburgh Press. Hoffman, A. J. 1999. "Institutional Evolution and Change: Environmentalism and the US Chemical Industry." ACADEMY OF MANAGEMENT JOURNAL 42:351-371. —. 2005. "Appendix C Business Decisions and the Environment: Significance, Challenges, and Momentum Of an Emerging Research Field." in Decision Making for the Environment: Social and Behavioral Science Research Priorities, edited by P. C. Stern and G. D. Brewer. —. 2006a. "Cooptation or Convergence in Field Level Dynamics: Social Movement Structure, Identity and Image." Ross School of Business. —. 2006b. Getting Ahead of the Curve: Corporate Strategies that Address Climate Change: Pew Center on Global Climate Change. Hoffinan, A. J. and M. J. Ventresca. 2002. Organizations, Policy, and the Natural Environment: Institutional and Strategic Perspectives: Stanford University Press. 186 Hooks, G. 1993. "The weakness of strong theories: the U. S. State's dominance of the World War 1] investment process." American sociological review 58:37-53. Hughes, T. P. 1983. Networks of Power: Electrification in Western Society, 1880-1930: Johns Hopkins University Press. Huxham, C. 1996. Creating Collaborative Advantage: Sage. J affee, D. 2007. Brewing Justice: Fair Trade Coflee, Sustainability, and Survival: University of California Press. J epperson, R. L. 1991. "Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutionalism." The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: 143- l 63. Knoke, D. 1990. Political Networks: The Structural Perspective: Cambridge University Press. Kollmuss, A. and J. Agyeman. 2002. "Mind the Gap: why do people act environmentally and what are the barriers to pro-environmental behavior?" Environmental Education Research 8:239-260. Konefal, J. 2007. "Saving the Oceans Via the Market: Social Movements in the Marketplace." Michigan State University. Dept. of Sociology. Kroll-Smith, S., V. Gunter, and S. Laska. 2000. "The Symbolic, The Physical, and Sociology: Analytic Stances and Theorizing Environments." American Sociologist 31:44-61. Laswell, H. 1936. "Who Gets What, When, and How." New York: Whittlesey House. Laumann, E. O., D. Knoke, and Y. H. Kim. 1985. "An Organizational Approach to State Policy Formation: A Comparative Study of Energy and Health Domains." American Sociological Review 50:1-19. Levy, D. L. and S. Rothenberg. 2002. "Heterogeneity and Change in Environmental Strategy: Technological and Political Responses to Climate Change in the Global Automobile Industry." Organizations, Policy and the Natural Environment: Institutional and Strategic Perspectives: 173-193. Lewis, T. L. 2000. "Transnational Conservation Movement Organizations: Shaping The Protected Area Systems of Less Developed Countries." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 5: 103-121 . Lough, Thomas S. 1996. "Energy analysis of the structures of industrial organizations." Energy 21:13]. 187 Lovins, A. B. and E. H. Thorndike. 1978. "Soft Energy Paths: Toward a Durable Peace." American Journal of Physics 46:868. Luhmann, N. 1989. Ecological Communication: University Of Chicago Press. Lyon, T. P. and J. W. Maxwell. 2004. Corporate Environmentalism and Public Policy: Cambridge University Press. Marsden, P. V. 2005. Recent developments in network measurement, vol. 8: Cambridge University Press. Mazur, A. and E. Rosa. 1974. "Energy and Life-Style." Science 186:607-610. McAdam, D., J. D. McCarthy, and M. N. Zald. 1996. "Introduction: Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures, and Framing Processes—Toward a Synthetic, Comparative Perspective on Social Movements." Comparative Perspectives on Social Movements: Political Opportunities, Mobilizing Structures, and Cultural F ramings: 1—20. McAdam, D., R. Scott, G. F. Davis, and M. N. Zald. 2005. "Social Movements and Organization Theory." Cambridge. McCright, A. M. and R. E. Dunlap. 2000. "Challenging Global Warming as a Social Problem: An Analysis of the Conservative Movement's Counter-Clairns." Social Problems 47:499-522. McLaughlin, P. 2001. "Toward an Ecology of Social Action: Merging the Ecological and Constructivist Traditions." Human Ecology Review 8:12-28. McLaughlin, P. and M. Khawaja. 2000. "The organizational dynamics of the U. S. environmental movement: Legitimation, resource mobilization, and political opportunity." Rural sociology 65:422-439. Melchert, L. 2007. "The Dutch sustainable building policy: A model for developing countries?" Building and Environment 42:893-901. Merton, R. K. 1968. "On Sociological Theories Of the Middle Range." Social Theory and Social Structurez39—72. Meyer, J. W. and B. Rowan. 1977. "Institutional organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony." American Journal of Sociology 83:340-363. Meyerson, D. 2003. Tempered Radicals: How Everyday Leaders Inspire Change at Work: Harvard Business School Press. 188 Miller, A. S. 1995. "Energy Policy from Nixon to Clinton: From Grand Provider to Market Facilitator." Environmental Law 25:715. Mizruchi, M. S. and D. M. Bey. 2005. "Corporate Control, Interfirm Relations, and Corporate Power." The Handbook of Political Sociology: States, Civil Societies, and Globalization. MOI, A. P. J. 1995. The Refinement of Production: Ecological Modernization Theory And the Chemical Industry: International Books. Mo], A. P. J. and G. Spaargaren. 2000. "Ecological modernisation theory in debate: A review." Environmental Politics 9:17-49. Murphy, G. 2005. "Coalitions and The Development of The Global Environmental Movement: A Double-Edged Sword." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 10:235-250. Nadel, S. 2002. "Appliance and Equipment Efficiency Standards." Annual Reviews in Energy and the Environment 27:159-192. Nadel, Steven. 1997. "The future of standards." Energy and Buildings 26:119. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. 2002, "President Announces Clear Skies Initiative", Retrieved 12/01/2008, 2008 (http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2002/02/20020214-5.html). Norberg-Bohm, V. 2000. "Creating Incentives for Environmentally Enhancing Technological Change: Lessons From 30 Years of US Energy Technology Policy." Technological Forecasting and Social Change 65: 125-148. O'Connor, J. 1973. "The Fiscal Crisis of the State." St. Martin's Press, New York. O'Toole, L. J. and K. J. Meier. 2004. "Desperately Seeking Selznick: Cooptation and the Dark Side Of Public Management in Networks." Public Administration Review 64:681-693. Oliver, CS. 2008. "Toxic Decisions: A Sociological Study Of the Contamination of U.S. Water Supplies by Methyl Tertiary Butly Ether (MTBE)." Department of Sociology, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Pacala, S. and R. Socolow. 2004. "Stabilization Wedges: Solving the Climate Problem for the Next 50 Years with Current Technologies." Pp. 968-972 in Science, vol. 305: American Association for the Advancement of Science. Parson, E. 2003. Protecting the Ozone Layer: Science and Strategy: Oxford University Press, USA. 189 Pellow, D. N. 2001. "Environmental Justice and the Political Process: Movements, Corporations, and the State." The Sociological Quarterly 42:47-67. Perrow, C. 1997. "Organizing for Environmental Destruction." Organization & Environment 10:66. —. 1999. Normal Accidents: Living with High-risk Technologies: Princeton University Press. Perz, S. G. 2007. "Reforrnulating Moderrrization-Based Environmental Social Theories: Challenges on the Road to an Interdisciplinary Environmental Science." Society & Natural Resources 20:415-430. Pfeffer, J. and G. R. Salancik. 1978. The External Control of Organisations:A resource Dependence Perspective. New York: Harper & Row. Powell, W. W. and P. DiMaggio. 1991. The New institutionalism in organizational analysis: Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Powell, W. W., D. R. White, K. W. Koput, and J. Owen-Smith. 2005. "Network Dynamics and Field Evolution: The Growth of Interorganizational Collaboration in the Life Sciences 1." American Journal of Sociology 110:1132-1205. Prakash, A. and M. Potoski. 2007. "Collective Action Through Voluntary Environmental Programs: A Club Theory Approach." Presthus, R. V. and R. Presthus. 1962. The Organizational Society: An Analysis and a Theory: Vintage books. Pulver, S. 2007. "Making Sense Of Corporate Environmentalism: An Environmental Contestation Approach to Analyzing the Causes and Consequences Of the Climate Change Policy Split in the Oil Industry." Organization & Environment 20:44. Roberts, T. and P. E. Grimes. 2002. "World-System Theory and the Environment: Toward a New Synthesis." Sociological Theory and the Environment: Classical Foundations, Contemporary Insights: 167—196. Rosa, E. A. 1998. "Metatheoretical foundations for post-normal risk." Journal of Risk Research 1:15-44. Rosen, C. M. and C. C. Sellers. 1999. "The Nature of the Firm: Towards an Ecocultural History of Business." Business History Review 73:577-600. Rosenfeld, A. H. 1999. "The Art of Energy Efficiency: Protecting the Environment with Better Technology." Annual Reviews in Energy and the Environment 24:33-82. 190 Scheinberg, A. 2003. "A change by any other name: Re-examining the urban recycling experience in North America and its implications for ecological modernisation theory." Environmental Politics 12:49-75. Schnaiberg, A. 1980. "Environment: from surplus to scarcity." New York. —. 1994. "The Political Economy of Environmental Problems and Policies: Consciousness, Conflict, and Control Capacity." Advances in Human Ecology 3:23-64. Schumacher, E. F. 1973. Small is Beautifirl: A Study of Economics as if People Mattered. London: Abakus. Scott, W. R., G. F. Davis, and W. Richard. 2007. Organizations and organizing: rational, natural, and open system perspectives: Pearson Prentice Hall. Selznick, P. 1966. TVA and the Grass Roots: A Study in the Sociology of Formal Organization: Harper & Row. Shrivastava, P. 1994. "Castrated Environment: Greening Organizational Studies." Organization Studies 15:705. Smil, V. 1994. Energy in World History: Westview Press. Sonnenfeld, D. A. 2002. "Social Movements and Ecological Modernization: The Transformation of Pulp and Paper Manufacturing." Development and Change 33:1-27. Sonnenfeld, D. A. and A. P. J. Mo]. 2002. "Globalization and the Transformation of Environmental Governance: An Introduction." American Behavioral Scientist 45:1318. Spaargaren, G. 1997. "The ecological modernization of production and consumption." Essays in Environmental Sociology. Stern, N. H. 2006. Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change: HM Treasury. Stern, R. N. and S. R. Barley. 1996. "Organizations and Social Systems: Organization Theory." Administrative Science Quarterly 41 : 146-62. Sussman, Frances and Randall Freed. 2008. "Adapting to Climate Change: A Business Approach." Pew Center on Global Climate Change, Arlington, VA. Tanner, C. 1999. "Constraints on Environmental Behavior." Journal of Environmental Psychology 19:145-157. 19] Taylor, F. W. 1916. "The principles of Scientific Management pp. 61-72 in Shafritz, JM & Ott, J S (eds.): Classics of Organisation Theory." Harcourt College Publishers. van den Hove, S., M. Le Menestrel, and H. C. de Bettignies. 2002. "The oil industry and climate change: strategies and ethical dilemmas." Climate Policy 2:3-18. Varone, F. and B. Aebischer. 2001. "Energy efficiency: the challenges of policy design." Energy Policy 29:615-629. Webber, C. A., R. E. Brown, and J. Koomey. 2000. "Savings estimates for the Energy Star® voluntary labeling program." Energy Policy 28:1137-1149. Weber, M. 1922. "Bureaucracy." Pp. 80-85 in Classics of Organization Theory, edited by J. M. Shafritz and J. S. Ott: Harcourt Brace Colle Publishers. Wondolleck, J. M. and S. L. Yaffee. 2000. Making Collaboration Work: Lessons from Innovation in Natural Resource Management: Island Press. ' York, R. 2006. "Ecological Paradoxes: William Stanley Jevons and the Paperless Office." HUMAN ECOLOGYREVIEW 13:143. York, R. and E. A. Rosa. 2003. "Key Challenges to Ecological Modernization Theory: Institutional Efficacy, Case Study Evidence, Units of Analysis, and the Pace of Eco-Efficiency." Organization & Environment 16:273. York, R., E. A. Rosa, and T. Dietz. 2003. "Footprints on the earth: The environmental consequences of modernity." American sociological review 68:279-300. York, R., E. Rosa, and T. Dietz. Forthcoming 2008. "Ecological Modernization Theory: Theoretical and Empirical Challenges." in The International Handbook of Environmental Sociology, edited by M. a. W. Redclift, G. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Zald, M. N. 2000. "Ideologically Structured Action: An Enlarged Agenda for Social Movement Research." Mobilization: An International Quarterly 5:1-16. 192 flirt“... 3 Illllllllllllll