ABSTRACT APPRAISAL OF ALTERNATIVE MODELS FOR ESTIMATION OF INDIRECT EMPLOYMENT AND PROFIT GAINS RESULTING FROM PUBLIC WATER PROJECT INVESTMENT By William Augustus Ward In June of 1969 the United States Water Resources Council issued a revised statement of policies and procedures for evaluating Federal water resource projects. The primary effect of the new procedures was to greatly broaden the concept of project benefits. In particular, the benefits previously defined as "primary" and "secondary" or "in— direct" were both lumped together into categories called "contributions to national income" and "regional development." The research reported herein dealt with the appraisal of secondary or indirect benefits. The literature review revealed three categories of secondary benefits: 1) The customary variety consisting of the multiplier impacts "inducedéby" and "stemmingefromv output changes; 2) ex- ternalities such as economies of scale and technological spillovers; and 3) dynamic secondary benefits sudh as socially engineering the human inputs. The latter two categories have been the least widely used and seemingly the most difficult to appraise. William Augustus Ward 2 It was decided to focus upon the appraisal of the "customary" variety which applied the aggregate demand multiplier concept. The literature review also revealed that most indirect benefit analyses violate both the compensation principle and the Opportunity cost concept. The multiplier analyses surveyed showed a marked ten- dency to under—value the opportunity cost Of labor and to over- estimate the real income changes. In most cases the benefits es- timated exceeded the change in the recipients ability to pay. In the study, argwrents against placing a zero opportunity cost on human and capital resources were presented. It was argued that _ only the changes in quasi-rents to capital and the chgges in labor wages stimulated by the project are benefits to peOple in the project region. An attempt was made to develOp an indirect benefit appraisal model which reflected these concepts. rIhe model used national input- Output coeficients and secondary data regarding wages and profits by sector and region. The conditions and assumptions under which the proposed model would be Operable were spelled out. A total of nineteen conditions and assumptions were identified. Key among these were: 1) the Opportunity costs of the factors involved, 2) the state of the national and local economies, 3) the source and alternative allocation of the Federal funds expended, and 14) the inter-regional and inter—job mobility of labor. Five of the nineteen assumptions were not specific to the proposed model, but were applicable to indirect benefit analysis in general. Two more related to input—output approaches in general. Several had the effect of pre-specifying parts of the result. William Augustus Ward 3 The model was applied to four different water resource projects. The results were compared.with the indirect benefits estimated for the same projects by eight other teams of analysts. The teams represented three major water resource agencies and four universities. Numerical estimates of indirect benefits differed widely between the teams of analysts. These differences were found to be largely attributable to: l) differing concepts of What constituted indirect benefits, and 2) differing assumptions regarding the macro-economic framework within which the projects were being appraised. Some of the indirect benefit categories applied by the teams of analysts were: 1) Opening up new farming Opportunities in the western United States so as to re-distribute population, 2) raising per capita incomes in the regions effected (ine tensive growth), 3) increasing the total_income Of the region even if the increase occurred without increasing the incomes Of individuals already in the region, and 4) increasing the stability of income. Some key iflh plicit assumptions regarding the macro-economic policy framework related to: 1) other programs to deal with income and.employment maintenance, and 2) the sources of the Federal funds spent and the methods used to collect those funds. The study indicates that great difficulty will be had in applying the expanded benefit categories to Federal water project appraisal. The difficulty boils down to fOur key tasks: 1. Making the indirect income concepts and methods of estimation fit into the display framework selected by the water Resources COuncil: a. The accounts display income changes for the project region and for the nation as a.whole and do not facilitate the display of changes in income to individuals, within or without the region, b. The accounts do not facilitate the display of income losses to other regions; William Augustus Ward u 2. Choosing the effects to display —- e.g., regional employment, regional income, new farming opportunities, net national income, and income stability - and selecting the weights to be assigned to each for project-by—project comparisons. This is a value judge— ment which must be made either by the analyst or by the political process; 3. Finding the data to apply existent methods and developing improved methods for estimating the indirect impacts; A. Developing the skills within the field staffs Of the water resource agencies to handle the complex concepts and estimation procedures involved in estimating indirect effects. APPRAISAL OF ALTERNATIVE MODELS FOR ESTIMATION OF INDIRECT EMPLOYMENT AND PROFIT GAINS RESULTING FROM PUBLIC WATER PROJECT INVESTMENT By William Augustus Ward A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree Of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 7 ‘ ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS There are many people who made contributions to this study. To enumerate all Of them would be impossible. Nevertheless, certain people made contributions over the life of the project which should be acknowledged. Among these are Dr. Larry Conner and Dr. Daniel Chappelle. In particular, thanks go to Dr. Allan Schmid who served as Chairman Of the guidance committee and thesis committee. Finally, a special debt of gratitude is owed to my wife, Kaye, whose continued encouragement played a major role in the completion of this study. TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Towards the Appraisal of Secondary Benefits. . . . . . . . . . Objectives. . . . . . . . . . II. SECONDARY BENEFITS DEFINED: A REVIEW. . . . The Customary View - The Multiplier . . Indirect Benefits as a Pecuniary thernality. . . . . . . . . . Primary and Secondary Benefits: Mutually Bxclusive?. Secondary Benefits - The "Externality' Approach . . . . . . . . . . "Dynamic" or Developmental Secondary Benefits . . . . . . . . . . Summary Of Secondary Benefit Classifications. . . . . . . III. SECONDARY BENEFITS, ECONOMIC RENT, AND THE COMPENSATION ABILITY PRINCIPLE. . . Wage Changes and Economic Rent. . . . . Economic Rent and the Compensation Ability Principle . . . . . A Working Definition of Secondary Benefits. . . . . . . . . . . IV. SOME APPROACHES TO SECONDARY BENEFIT EVALUATION: A REVIEW . . . . . . . . . . iii Page 10 12 14 17 22 24 35 39 47 50 SS iv Chapter Page Secondary Benefits and Economic Impact Analysis . . . . . . . . . . 55 Impact Analysis and "Customary" Secondary Benefits. . . . . . . . . 56 Multiplier Analysis . . . . . . . . 60 Keynesian Multipliers . . . . . . . 62 "Induced" and "Induced-by": A Note on Terminology. . . . . . . . . . . 69 The Economic Base Multiplier. . . . 70 The Comparative Projection Approach . . . . . . . . . . . 78 Index Of Internal Purchases . . . . 84 From-to Analysis. . . . . . . . . . 86 Input-Output Analysis . . . . . . . 89 Output Multipliers . . . . . . 94 Type I (Direct-Indirect) Income Multipliers. . . . 97 Type II (Direct-Indirect-Induced) Multipliers . . . . . . . 103 Input-Output and Secondary Benefits: An Overview. . 108 Linear Programming. . . . . . . . . 113 Regional Linear Programming. . 113 Inter-regional Linear Programming . . . . . . . 114 River Basin Planning Models. . 114 Input-Output as a Linear Program . . . . . . . . . 115 Secondary Benefits and the Multiplier: A Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116 Chapter Page V. ESTIMATING SECONDARY FACTOR INCOME CHANGES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 Foreword. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 Estimating Wage Changes . . . . . . . . 127 The Wage Component of Value Added. . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 The Wage Rent Coefficient . . . . . 134 Estimating Profit Changes . . . . . . . 136 The Profit Component of Value Added. . . . . . . . . . . . . 136 Rounds of Expansion and Benefit Creditability . . . . . . . . . . . 142 Associated Investments. . . . . . . 143 Inelasticities of Supply. . . . . . 144 Adjusting the Multiplier. . . . . . 145 Regional Coefficients and Purchases . . 147 Differing Requirements. . . . . . . 148 Localizing Purchases. . . . . . . . 149 National and Local Industries. 153 Localization Ratio . . . . . . 155 Applying the Model. . . . . . . . . . . 157 The Trenton Channel Project . . . . 157 The Computation Procedure . . . . . . . 158 Induced-by Benefits . . . . . . . . 158 Stemming-From Benefits. . . . . . . 164 Construction Impacts: Induced-By . 169 Trenton Channel Project Secondary Benefits Summarized . . . . . . . . 171 vi Chapter The Underlying Assumptions of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Assumptions Common to Multiplier Analysis. . . . . . . . . . . . . Assumptions Common to Input-Output MOdeISO O O O O O O O O O O O I 0 Additional Assumptions from Conventions in Rent Model . . . . . . . . . . VI. A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF TWELVE SECONDARY BENEFIT APPRAISALS. . . . . . . . . . . Overview . . . Trenton Channel Project Michigan State University Test Team. . . . . . . Corps Of Engineers Test Team. Stonewall Jackson Reservoir . Corps Of Engineers Test Team. Cornell University Test Team. Poteau Watershed Project. Corps of Engineers TSSt Team. Soil Conservation Test Team . . . . Mountain Home Project . . . . . Corps of Engineers Test Team. . . . University Of Wisconsin Test Team . Effects of Differing Approaches on Secondary Benefit Estimates . . . . Secondary Benefits Compared to Primary Benefits . . . . . . . Regional Versus National Input-Output Coefficients . . . . . . . . . . Page 172 174 176 176 182 182 193 194 197 202 203 210 219 220 225 234 235 244 249 254 257 vii Chapter Page Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259 VII. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS. . . . . . . . . . . 262 Review of the Study Objectives. . . . . 262 The Estimation Of Secondary Benefits. . 264 The Rent Model. . . . . . . . . . . 264 Recommendations for Further Study . . . 267 Some Further Refinements of the MOdelo I O O I I O I O O O O O 269 Construct Local Input-Output Models. . . . . . . . . . 269 Detail of Job Requirements . . 271 Use Linear Programming to Restrain Gains. . . . . . 271 SOURCES CITED. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274 APPENDIX . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 281 LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1. After-Tax Profits Per Dollar of Sales Compared With Before Tax Profit Rates Reduced by Fifty Per Cent . . . . . 184 2. Trenton Channel Project: Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185 3. Stonewall Jackson Reservoir: Outline Of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation. . . . . . . . . . . . 187 4. Poteau Watershed Project: Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . 189 5. Mountain Home Project: Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . 190 6. Estimates of Regional and National Secondary Benefits: Comparison of Rent Model and Approaches Used by Others . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 192 7. Primary and Secondary Benefit Estimates from Eight Appraisals: Regional and National Accounts . . . . . . . . . . 255 viii LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1. Wage Determination and Rent Accrual Where the Elasticity of Supply Equals Zero (ES= 0) . . . . . '4' . . . 40 2. Wage Determination, Surplus and Rent Accrual Where the Elasticity of Supply is Variable [Eé = f(Qs)]. . . 44 ix CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION In its report1 to the Water Resources Council in June of 1969, the Special Task Force on Evaluation Procedures presented a greatly expanded concept Of benefits to be con- sidered in the evaluation Of Federal water projects. The motivation for the report and the revision Of benefit con- cepts was reportedly the passage in recent years of several laws relating to the Federal water program.2 As a result of these new laws, it was felt that the general guidelines pre- sented in Senate Document 973 (the currently-governing poli- cies and procedures document) would need to be updated to encompass the "broadened" national Objectives signalled by Congressional enactment Of the new laws. The broadened national Objectives which were to be fostered by the Federal water program were classified as 1) national income Objectives, 2) regional development objec- tives, 3) environmental objectives, and 4) well-being Ob- jectives. It was proposed that each of these be made ex- plicit considerations in water project evaluations, and that the value Of each project be judged on the basis of its contribution to one or more of these Objectives. It was suggested that the Old distinction between "primary” and 2 ”secondary" or "indirect" benefits be abandoned and that in their place the concept of "contributions to the national income Objective" be adopted. This was felt to be "con- sistent with the evaluation principle requiring the identi- fication and measurement of all beneficial effects . . ." It was proposed that those benefits formerly referred to as 'Secondary" and "indirect" now be discussed in terms of 'production externalities" and "resource unemployment" bene— fits,4 and that, rather than be treated only in side calcu- lations, any contributions to national income from these sources should be accounted for in the national income ob- jective account. Production externalities were considered to prevail when There exist economies of scale in production for industries affected by the project output when such economies do not exist in any activities which may contract. Under this condition production units may ~ be Operated at a more efficient level or interrelated processes may be better coordinated including the elimination of bottlenecks to the efficient expansion gfother actTVities. _5' ‘— Resource unemployment benefits could be expected to prevail when Otherwise unemployed or underemployed resources (labor, fixed capital and resource capital) may be used or better employed as a result of the developments oc- Casioned by the project. This may come about as a direct result of project construction, Operation, maintenance and replacement or as an indirect result of the use Of project outputs. This latter effect occurs when the expansion Of industries directly or indirectly using project outputs draw heavily upon similarly unemployed or underemployed resources. Though a potentially major addition to what was the old "national efficiency" or primary benefit account was 3 being made, the national income Objective account was still considered to be a principal Objective measure of project value in light Of which contributions to other Objectives were to be considered. The addition of environmental con— sideration, regional development considerations, and con- siderations concerning the well being Of people were added as additional Objectives to be evaluated as competitors wfith national income Objectives. However, the national in— come objective account was also greatly expanded by the addition of "secondary" impacts to that category of benefits. The current status of theory, research methods and data sources concerning the evaluation of secondary effects was such that the Task Force acknowledged the difficulty surrounding the evaluation of these impacts, especially that of production externalities. Thus, while some general recommendations concerning the analysis of unemployed re- source benefits were made, no attempt was made to present a format for the analysis of production externalities. The "bottleneck" thesis forms the basis for much Of the analysis Of secondary impacts, since it allows the ‘assignment of cause for secondary output expansion to the water project (which supposedly eliminates the bottleneck). While not all water resource agencies formerly included the evaluation Of secondary benefits due to bottleneck elimination in their analyses, explicit consideration was often given to the elimination of production bottlenecks as a rationale for public investment. The proposed evaluation 4 procedures would allow for the inclusion of the expansionary effects Of such elimination as explicit project benefits. By expanding the concept Of income effects to in- clude indirect or secondary impacts, the Task Force sought to comply with newly-enacted legislation which made re- gional development an explicit goal Of the Appalachian water resource program. Unemployed resource benefits were expected to occur largely in the case of projects built in depressed regions. Benefits from scale economics would be expected to occur more readily in local economies xflfich were Operating at very low levels Of output. The employment gains from breaking production bottlenecks would be greatest where large volumes of resources were unem- ployed. The division of the income effects into a Regional Ikwelopment Account and a National Income Account made the nation's regional deveIOpment objectives explicit and made it possible to explicitly trade-Off national income for regional income. However, it also made necessary techni- ques for estimating both regional and national impacts of water resource projects. In the past, only the Bureau of Reclamation Of the United States Department of the Interior (referred to hereinafter as the Bureau) had attempted to evaluate indirect income effects of water projects. In do- ing so, the Bureau considered that Congress had assigned it the mission of developing the arid regions of the West- ern United States; thus, regional development benefits were 5 treated as synonomous with national benefits. Transfer of income to the region was a primary goal of the Bureau's program, and little attempt was made to estimate the net national impact or to determine the efficiency of the transfer.7 The Bureau developed a "model" for evaluating the in- direct effects of its reclamation efforts. The model con- sisted of a set Of coefficients intended to represent the value added in processing outputs and producing the pur- chased inputs for the major agricultural commodities grown in the region. These coefficients were used in estimating the indirect income generated by the increased agricultural output on farms using project-supplied water. The Bureau's approach to benefit evaluation has been widely criticized.8 The Bureau's model would not appear to be a generally ac- ceptable means for dealing with the expanded concept of benefits under the new proposed procedures. Towards the Appraisal 2£_Secondary Benefits Many other "models" for appraising secondary benefits have been proposed in recent years. These models can gener- ally be divided into three groups: 1) multiplier models, 2) externality models, and 3) dynamic models (these three groups will be discussed more fully in Chapter II). The most popular has been the multiplier model (these are dis- cussed in Chapter IV). The Bureau's approach has been classified as a multiplier model. 6 Perhaps the most misused concept in economics has been that of the multiplier. As a result, many prominent econo- mists view with disdain the proposals to use multiplier con- cepts in the appraisal of Federal water projects. This is unfortunate since some aspects of multiplier analysis offer great promise in appraising one kind Of secondary benefit vflfich most economists would agree needs to be better ap- praised: the real economic costs of factors used and Of factors directly stimulated to use by Federal water projects. The problem of appropriately shadow-pricing resources is closely tied to the basic static multiplier concept. A mmjor purpose of this study is to demonstrate the link be- tween the very simple economic concepts of 1) Opportunity costs, 2) economic rent, and 3) multiplier analysis, and to develop a model which utilizes these concepts in appraising static indirect benefits. Objectives The Objectives of the present study are 1. To survey, evaluate, and synthesize the current status of theory regarding secondary or indirect benefits; 2. To identify the elements in Objective one above which can be forged into a generally applicable model which a) can be applied to all or most Federal water projects, b) uses generally available secondary data, c) makes explicit the assumptions and conditions under which it is Operable; 7 To demonstrate and test the model by applying it to four test case projects; TO compare the model test results with the results ob- tained by other test teams and to identify the reasons for differing test results from the several analyses; To evaluate the applicability of the model in light of the results obtained in meeting objective four. 8 Footnotes 1. Procedures for Evaluation of Water and Related Land Resource PrOJects: Report Ofithe Special TaEk Force on EValuation Procedures to the water Resource'CounC1l. (wash1ngton: June 1969)’. 2. Ibid., pp. 6-10. 3. United States Senate, 87th Congress, 2nd Session, Policies, Standards and Procedures in the Formulation, Evaluation, andIReview of Plans for Use andeevelppment of Water and Related Land Resources, (Washington: 1962). 4. Procedures for Evaluation . . . , Op cit, 39-41. 5. Ibid., 42. 6. Ibid., 43. 7. George S. Tolley, "Impact of Public Resource Development on Agricultural Production and Income," Pro- ceedingsof the Aggicultural Economics and Rural SOCTOIogy Section, Assoc1atlon of Southern AgricfilturaIIWO—kers, 8. See especially Tolley, Op cit. CHAPTER II SECONDARY BENEFITS DEFINED: A REVIEW The term "secondary benefits” as generally used in the water resources field refers to "The increase in the value Of goods and services which indirectly result from the project under conditions expected with the project as compared to those without the project."1 While primary benefits include only the value Of outputs which are pro- duced directly by the project, secondary benefits include the increased outputs (values) which result from the re- percussions of the project outputs upon the rest of the economy. Thus, while the analysis of primary benefits is by nature micro-economic, the analysis of secondary bene- fits has been considered macro-economic in approach.2 The concept of secondary benefits found in the lit- erature is not monolithic. Much controversy persists among economists regarding the nature, existence and means of evaluation. A large part Of the disagreement stems from the existence of more than one type of secondary benefit. Most authors have not satisfactorily delimited the cate- gory of benefits they were discussing nor the assumptions under which the subject was being treated. Often authors 10 have mixed into their discussion more than one type of bene- fit. The resulting confusion and disagreement between authors has been extensive. Basically, one can divide secondary benefits into three different kinds: 1) the "customary" variety relating largely to multiplier effects, 2) the "externality" variety which relate mostly to economies of scale and the effects of "spillovers", and 3) "dynamic" secondary benefits which relate to changes in the shape of production functions, changes in "the human factor" and basic institutional ef- fects. These three categories are not clearly defined and adhered to, as the following sections will show. For exam- ple, it is not clear whether "technological externalities" should go into the second or the third category. Further, the treatment of aggregate demand multiplication could be also viewed as a pecuniary spillover, which could place it in the second category. Nevertheless, the tripartite division is helpful in interpreting the literature regard- ing secondary benefits. It is especially helpful in under- standing the basis of the disagreements between different authors. The Customary View - The Multiplier The customary approach to secondary benefits has generally divided them into two classes, following largely the convention of the Bureau Of Reclamation: 1) those "induced-by" the increased factor requirements occasioned 11 by the project, and 2) those "stemming-from" the added pro- cessing, etc., of the direct project outputs.3 The first class can be sub-divided into a) those "induced-by" factor requirements for constructing, operating and maintaining the project, and b) those "induced-by" the complementary relationship between the water-based goods and other factors in the production of the direct benefits. An example of the latter is the induced sales of fertilizer as a result of increased water availability due to an irrigation proj- ect. The ”induced-by" and "stemming-from" effects can be classified as demand effects and supply effects,-respec- tively.4 The former occur through the transmission Of (derived) demand from the project outputs through the pro- ducers of the factors which go into intermediate products to meet those demands. The latter occur through the in- creased availability Of factors to later stages in the marketing process. Ostensibly, since the supply of factors at the project-level stage has increased, the supplies of outputs at successive stages will increase. Both of these effects generate household income at each stage in the form of wages and profits. The indirect benefit is the change in real income realized as a result of the project. Clark, Grant and Kelso (referred to hereafter as the Panel) in their report5 to the Bureau of Reclamation advise that, since supply and demand act jointly to determine in- come, stemming-from effects and induced-by effects should not be added in estimating the value Of secondary benefits 12 from the national vieWpOint. They argue that stemming-from effects are a special form of supply effect which pre- supposEs a demand for the increased output. Further, the impetus of the two effects occur at different times in the life of the project. Part of the aggregate demand effect (induced) occurs as a result of construction expenditures, while the supply effect (stemming) occurs after project Operation has begun and project outputs are forthcoming, often with somewhat of a lagged response.6 Also, since the factors demanded by the project differ from the factors produced by it, traditional macro-economic aggregate supply and demand analysis tends to Obscure the multitude Of inter- actions and transactions necessary to establish a new equi- librium. The resource movements involved in those pecuniary interactions make the determination of net income effects very difficult to get at. Indirect Benefits as a Pecuniary Externality McKean7 discusses indirect benefits as a form of pecuniary spillover or externality. He concludes that, in the presence of full employment, the net national benefits from such spillovers will be zero; the incidence of rents will shift so that some individuals benefit and some lose, but the net change in income in the absence of technological spillovers or economies of scale will be zero. However, if resources are unemployed or under-employed, there exist possibilities for indirect benefits to occur. He does not 13 view such existence as a sufficient cause for a project to create indirect benefits, however. Neither does their existence solve the problem Of separating out the net changes in real income due to employment of previously un- employed factors from shifts in the incidence of scarcity rents, where such changes may be widespread and individually very small. McKean argues that, generally, the project analyst should include, in the national account, only technological spillovers, and should only consider pecuniary spillovers (to McKean, indirect benefits) if involuntary unemployment of a very long range nature is expected to exist in the absence of the project. He argues that in most situations the time lag between project analysis and construction is such that unemployment which existed at the analysis stage might well have disappeared by the time construction begins.8 The McKean definition of indirect benefits appears to only include aggregate demand effects and pecuniary ex- ternalities. He treats technological externalities and economies of scale under a second group of effects. "The position taken [by McKean] . . . is that the two general types of spillover -- technological and pecuniary -- are, "10 He in principle distinguishable and mutually exclusive. does not believe that secondary benefits generally prevail for the nation as a whole after all project effects are netted between all resource owners and all regions. Only under very special conditions of severe unemployment and l4 factor immobility will any net positive effects occur for the nation as a whole, and those will be much smaller than traditionally claimed.11 The Secondary Benefit Controversy There is some disagreement among economists concerning the question Of the existence of secondary or indirect bene- fits. While that portion Of economic theory is so under- deVeloped as to allow for much controversy,12 perhaps some part of that disagreement revolves around the confusion surrounding the inclusiveness of the term ”secondary bene- 13 take a fits." As pointed out above, McKean and others very restrictive view of the term. The tendency among this group is to think only in terms of aggregate demand analysis which, under certain conditions, can lead to an increase in national income. Another group, to which the Water Resource Council Task Force seems to belong,14 view secondary bene- fits as inclusive Of all possible economic effects beyond the valuation of the direct project outputs, including scale economies, technological externalities, aggregate demand effects, aggregate supply effects, etc. Thus, the latter group tend to look more favorably upon the possi- bility of secondary benefits in water resource projects. Primagy and Secondarnyenefits: Mutually Exclusive? While the difference in inclusiveness of the defini- tion Of secondary benefits contributes to the controversy 15 over real net national effects, it is not the only factor. An additional element is the disagreement over the sort of assumptions one should make about the future. Some analysts assume that general fiscal policy and public programs will be managed so as to promote steady growth, full employment, and factor mobility. Under these assumptions, long range resource unemployment problems disappear (or are obfuscated). Thus, only the demand multiplier effects Of the construction expenditures are perhaps relevant; and the length of the planning period is such that fiscal management might have already eliminated that source of unemployment benefits.15 The necessity for these assumptions is seen as the realiza- tion that, in the absence of steady growth and "adequate" levels of aggregate demand, the direct project outputs will constitute excess supply; thus, the assumptions which give value to the primary benefits are interpreted as negating the possibility of indirect benefits. The difficulties Of the unemployment-adequate demand dichotomy which plague the analyst under the growth- employment-mobility assumption can be handled through a minor alteration in that assumption. The difficulty lies in the all-or-nothing interpretation of the assumption-~i.e., that one can not have both a growth in demand and unemploy- ment or immobility. Such a situation can exist, however. Since the growth in demand is the principal factor upon which the valuation of primary outputs is based, then one can have both primary and secondary benefits prevailing, if 16 there is unemployment, as a result of factor immobility. Thus, the assumption Of factor immobility has come to play a large role in the justification for and evaluation of net secondary benefits. Some discussion has developed over the extent to which factor immobility should serve as a basis for secondary benefit analysis. On the one hand, it is realized that less than perfect mobility contributes to market imperfections which can allow unemployment in some areas or markets to coexist with inflationary demand in crther areas or markets. Practically all analysts agree tliat unemployed or underemployed factors constitute a vwaste Of resources. However, the disagreement comes from ‘tlle interpretations concerning the temporal nature of the Unemployment. Some argue that, if the unemployment and market imperfections are short-run in nature, then the (:1W3ation of indirect impacts in those areas via public in- VeIStment would thwart the Operation of the incentive system L1Don which the market system Operates.16 The effects of SuCh a policy in the long run would be to undermine the r“arket system. Others interpret many of the market imper- :Ef3ctions as long run imperfections. Thus, the policy pre- SSCFTiption is to pinpoint such areas and dose in public in- \’€>Stments designed to create indirect employment Of the ()1iherwise long-range unemployed. 17 Secondary Benefits - The "Externality" Approach Margolis argues that the Bureau Of Reclamation program cannot be justified on the basis of primary benefits alone. Ruther, the traditional "stemming-from" and ”induced-by" sort Of approach, when properly done, would not in most cases lead to a justification Of most irrigation projects. However, when one considers the possible external economies due to denser settlement, economies of scale due to larger lxocal markets, improvements in transportation, etc., the Irregram of the Bureau becomes more justifiable. Thus, Nkargolis concludes, "The proper framework within which to (iirscuss secondary benefits is the theory of external econo- nflires."17 He would not limit the discussion to pecuniary ex- 17—el‘it‘na1ities but would include other forms Of externalities as well. The Water Resource Council Task Force, in effect, 1nStitutionalizes the inclusion of externalities in the (1‘3ifinition of secondary benefits.18 They apparently accept 1:}IGB judgement that net national secondary benefits do not ()Slcnir from project investments in the absence of unemploy- Inern: or external economies. Thus, "secondary benefits will theSiult in contributions to national income when either of 1:}1€> two general conditions are expected to prevail." These gel'leral conditions are: l. Externalities--There exist economies of scale in production for industries affected by the project output when such economies do not exist in any activi- ties which may contract. Under this condition 18 production units may be Operated at a more efficient evel or interrelated processes may be better coordi- nated including the elimination of bottlenecks to the efficient expansion of other activities. 2. Resource unemployment--Otherwise unemployed or underemployed resources (Tabor, fixed capital and resource capital) may be used or better employed as a result of the developments occasioned by the project. This may come about as a direct result of project con- struction, Operation, maintenance, and replacement or as an indirect result of the use Of project outputs. This latter effect occurs when the expansion Of in- dustries directly or indirectly-using project outputs drawn upon'igmilarly unemployed or underemployed I TESOUI‘CBS . Under the "Externalities",heading the Task Force lists ‘two general conditions under which the public investments Inay generate net secondary benefits. The first is that of ciifferent economies of scale between contracting and ex- IDanding industries. In terms of benefits, the real dif- fierence between the net values of the outputs would appear tile relevant concept. The Task Force realized the diffi- Clulty of determining and measuring benefits due to scale economies. and did not present a format for evaluating tfllem.20 The second category of externalities relates to the eilimination of bottlenecks. Secondary benefits would exist jfif the project directly or indirectly stimulated the ex- IPEInsion of output Of some factor which had effectively Llfiimited the expansion of other activities. Such a situation might occur in a water supply project in which the water was ‘1 critical input into one product which was a critical in- I3111: into a second product. In this case, the provision 19 of water might stimulate the expansion of both activities, given the existence of effective demand for the outputs of both. The degree to which the water-related product con- tributed to such expansion and the extent to which one might credit the added income to the project would depend not only upon the marginal rates of substitution between the "critical" factors and other inputs but also upon the assumptions made regarding alternative means of providing those factors, and the development of substitutes (in- cluding a substitute technology), etc. All of the ex- Ipansion would be creditable only under the very restrictive Eissumptions of 1) zero substitutability between factors 13rovided at all levels of expansion, 2) no alternative Ineans of providing the initial critical factors, and 3) no Ilew'technology which would effectively substitute for the Ciritical factors would develop during the life of the Irroject. In addition, since the bottleneck elimination is 1-argely a supply effect, it is assumed that effective demand will exist for the outputs over the relevant period. In actuality, the bottleneck elimination benefits Efre very much akin to the traditional "stemming-from" bene- fits in the Bureau of Reclamation procedures. For the stem- ming benefits to be valid, the same process of reasoning and assumptions outlined above would be necessary. In the case of the Bureau, the basic project output :155 irrigation. The principal direct benefits come from in- C1‘eased agricultural output. There is little doubt that 20 agricultural outputs are the basic factor in a food proces- sing operation and that little factor substitution is possible, except between agricultural commodities. The same is true for succeeding operations to the final market. Thus, the Bureau procedure has been largely in keeping with that part of the requirements. However, a basic issue has been overlooked. That is, does a shortage of agricultural outputs exist which serves as a bottleneck to the expansion (of food processing and succeeding activities? The apparent zrnswer in light of the agricultural surpluses is that, in ‘teamw of national agricultural output, such a bottleneck (ices not exist. Whether or not such a bottleneck exists ill terms of regional expansion is perhaps another issue, llowever -- an issue which belongs in the discussion of the regional development effects of indirect benefits, since 1311ch.expansion in the project region would be expected to 53$! offset by a contraction in some other farming region.21 (3’1 the other hand, if there did exist a shortage of agri- <2llltural products, nationwide and if that shortage did ZEFDrce the Operation of food processing plants at inef- :Eficient levels, then net national indirect benefits could t3€3 realized as a result of such irrigation projects. Thus, ‘tlle validity of the principle stands, in spite of the im- I)‘JT‘Oper manner in which it has been applied on occasion. The Resource Unemployment benefits rightly belong under the customary variety of secondary benefits discussed €1131 60 multiplier framework. Most of the approaches discussed below could be used in the estimation of "stemming-from" effects as well. Multiplier Analyeis In very general terms, a "multiplier" constitutes an expression of the relationship between changes in one variable in association with a given change in another variable. Thus, one might view a multiplier as simply a "coefficient" in a functional equation which relates changes in the dependent variable to changes in the inde- pendent variable. As used in economics, "multipliers” generally refer to the relationship between some welfare-related dependent variable and an independent "policy" variable which is sub- ject to manipulation from without. The most common of the welfare-related variables have been those of employment and income. Their determinants have ranged from "govern- ment expenditures" to the "export base" of the relevant economic unit. There are many such relationships in econo- mics, with several means for constructing multipliers to represent most of them. Thus, one should be wary of such terms as "The Multiplier," which is often encountered in Federal water resource project reports and, at times, in other economics literature. A great part of the attraction which multiplier analy- sis seems to hold stems, no doubt, from the simplicity and ci- in p&\ a 61 apparent logic of the process by which multipliers are gen- erally derived. For most multipliers, a knowledge of simple algebra is sufficient for one to understand the mathemati- cal relationships involved. By the same token, the same simple algebra is generally sufficient for the student to derive the expressed multiplier himself or derive another on his own. For example, the original Keynesian investment- income multiplier is sufficiently simple in concept that normal procedure in economics principles courses is to have students derive it for themselves. At the same time, the algebra involved lends to the derivation process an aura of mathematical logic which tends to create an il- lusion of a great revelation,8 when, in fact, the "multi- plier" might be nothing more than another way of stating a tautology.9 Keynes, though himself accused Of the same fault by Haberler and others, warns against the obfuscation of important relationships by "a maze of pretentious and 10 One should interpret apparent mathe- unhelpful symbols." matical relationships with some caution lest he interpret a snapshot specification of an existent situation as a fundamental long run identity or functional relationship. The warning concerning the regression fallacy is not new to economists; indeed, it is included in practically all introductory texts. Thus, whether one should interpret a ”relationship” between farm income and non-farm income, for example, as a fundamental multiplier identity is a question which cannot be answered by simply stating that "total 62 11 The careful income = farm income + non-farm income." process by which causation is established is not present in this statement alone. Keynesian Multipliers Though the original presentation of the multiplier 12 it was John concept is generally credited to R. F. Kahn, Maynard Keynes who brought the concept to fruition in his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. In Chapter Ten Keynes presented his now famous investment- income multiplier which expressed a relationship between equilibrium income and investment. In a closed system in which investment constituted the only exogenously determined variable, changes in equilibrium income were given by the product of investment change and the multiplier, defined as the reciprocal of one minus the marginal propensity to consume, or TTMFC' Though Keynes discussed altering effects upon the multiplier by such factors as foreign trade pay- ments (later called "leakages") and durable-nondurable goods composition of purchases, the basic Keynesian multi- plier remains as originally stated. Though the original, simplified derivation of the Keynesian multiplier stressed the effects of exogenous changes in investment upon the economy, the concept may be applied to any form of exogenous infusion of expenditures. Thus, it is particularly useful in looking at the effects upon regional income of a given level of expenditure in 63 public works originating outside of the region, such as ex- penditures by the Federal government for construction of a water resource project. To estimate the secondary changes in income using the Keynesian multiplier, one would first have to establish the marginal prOpensity to consume. If one were largely interested in regional income changes (as, for example, one might be in applying the considerations dictated by the Appalachian Development Act), one would need to know the regional MPC. Having determined that, the process of estimating the secondary income changes would be a fairly simple one. It should be emphasized, however, that the determination of the MPC is seldom a simple task and would require a large scale research effort in and of itself. If the MPC of the region in which the expenditure occurred were different from that of the nation as a whole, the secondary income changes would not represent simply shifts in income between regions; there might also occur net increases or declines in national income as a result 13 has demonstrated that if of those shifts. J. S. Chipman the MPC for all regions were equal, the inter-regional multiplier would reduce to the national multiplier. Then there would be no problem of trading off relative changes in regional income with absolute changes in national in- come. If the MPC of the project region were greater than that of the nation as a whole, national income would be in- creased by virtue of the shift in expenditures. Richardson _-.r 1"" .fiui 9.9 . ‘5'. 9n) '9 64 notes that, since most underdeveloped regions tend to have a very high MPC, national income would be maximized if the increase in government expenditures were concentrated in those regions.14 While first round expenditures would perhaps be greater in such regions, "leakages" would also tend to be greater. Thus, while national income might be greater, the region in question would probably realize little of the gains in income beyond the first round of expenditures. An obvious difficulty with the simple Keynesian multiplier is that it does not consider such factors as imports and other leakages which exist in open systems. Thus, there are serious limitations to its use in regional analysis. When other factors such as the industrial com- position of the region, regional input-output relation- ships, and local purchasing propensities are considered, the marginal propensity to consume becomes only one of many factors operating upon the level of regional income. In- deed, if the MPC is related to the state of develOpment while the volume of leakage is related in an inverse fashion, as would appear to be the case, the simple Key- nesian multiplier could be quite misleading in terms of re- gional income effects of exogenous investment. The degree of aggregation involved in the determina- tion of a single marginal propensity to consume creates the kind of problems involved in all such aggregations. First, there is the problem of different consumption V - .u‘ .3 1 ’ v 65 patterns between different groups of income recipients. As a result, it makes some difference as to what groups the initial income changes accrue. If there is a systematic bias towards skilled craftsmen, for example, whose incomes tend to be higher than average, then the relevant MPC might be quite different from the average propensity to consume. At least the first round of expenditures should take this fact into consideration. Secondly, it matters what the composition of purchases is for both the exogenous infusion and for the ensuing household purchases. Keynes realized the difficulties involved with durable goods purchases, for example, which are normally taken "on order." The lags in- volved at both the consumption and production stages for durable goods create difficulties. In the case of Federal water resource projects a large volume of the expenditures involved are directed towards durable goods industries.15 The problems created by the differing "velocities of circulation" (or "duration of the rounds") are substantial in determining both the magnitude and duration of the sig- nificant multiplier effects. As in interpreting all multipliers, one should ask the question pf exactly what is being multiplied. In this case, the "welfare-related" variable that one is attempting to change is income. Whether or not those income changes represent commensurate changes in real welfare, however, is not answered by the analysis. This must be answered from without and in consideration of other factors. This 66 is true because of the manner in which the multiplier oper- ates. While one often hears the Keynesian multiplier de- scribed as an "income" multiplier, it multiplies income directly under only very Special cOnditions. The Keynesian ' multiplier (and most other "income” multipliers) is an ag- gregate demand multiplier. Thus, for it to be effective, certain conditions relating to aggregate supply must be met. In short, aggregate supply must either be perfectly elastic or it must shift (as a result of the investment, ostensibly) by the same amount as does aggregate demand for the multi- plier effectsato'be felt full force without being partially absorbed through inflation. For the full value of the in- come payments to represent real changes in welfare to the recipients, the opportunity costs of those‘factors must have been zero. Thus, the real welfare effects (secondary benefits) of public investments are consistently overstated by the Keynesian multiplier in all except this very special case. While practically all secondary impact study reports begin with a discussion of the Keynesian multiplier concept, few of them utilize the pure Keynesian version in their analyses.. The common disclaimer by which the analyst proceeds to another approach concerns the difficulty of obtaining data (especially at the local or regional level) on the marginal prOpensity to consume and the imprecision of such data, when available. As a result, most impact studies which purport to utilize the Keynesian multiplier D'. 67 in fact only utilize the Keynesian method of derivation. That method has been discussed above and some of the pit- falls delineated. The following example should demon- strate some of these pitfalls. In their article on farm-non-farm income linkages, Mirakhor and Orazem discuss the development of the multi- plier concept. They quote a definition of the multiplier by Oskar Lange as ". . . the marginal effect of a change of one economic variable upon another economic variable, of which the first is a component." From this definition they conclude that ". . . if it is possible to divide an eco- nomic variable into its different components, it is per- missable to determine the changes that take place in the original variable as a result of a change in one of its components."16 The authors then proceed to set up an in- come identity similar to the Keynesian income identity. This, however, shows total income as composed Of farm in- come and non-farm income. From this identity, "multipliers" are derived which show the relationship between "changes in farm income" and "changes in total income." In fact, the multipliers" are nothing more than the tautological state- ment which Haberler warned against in his discussion of the Keynesian derivation. Though Mirakhor and Orazen use correlation analysis to demonstrate the implied relationship between farm in- come and non-farm income via their "multiplier," no where do they show the logical process by which farm income 68 changes "cause" non-farm income changes. As discussed earlier in this chapter, correlation analysis does not establish causation between variables: it merely demon- strates the degree of similarity in the manner in which they change. Thus, the presentation of statistical analy- sis with their "farm-non—farm income multiplier" is not sufficient to rebut the Haberler criticism but rather further points up the danger of the regression fallacy. An additional point concerning the pure Keynesian multiplier bears mentioning in closing this section. That point regards the part played by the marginal propensity to consume in determining the equilibrium level of income in the Keynesian system. If one forgets about the aggregate supply side of the Keynesian system (as too often multiplier analysts do), an apparent disagreement among growth theo- rists and Keynesianites develOpes. This apparent dis- agreement should serve to illustrate the problems posed by the uncritical acceptance of multiplier analysis in im- pact evaluation. The Keynesian multiplier holds that an inverse relationship exists between the marginal propensity to save and income growth in the system. That is, the less saving there is in the economy, the greater will be the level of equilibrium income. However, most of the growth models developed by international development economists made savings (rather than consumption) the prime mover of growth in the underdeveloped world. Thus, the policy pre- scription in the growth models is to somehow reduce the 69 marginal propensity to consume and to raise savings out of current income. The similarity in this dichotemy to that between the Classicists and the Marginalists over the determinant of market prices is striking. To one group the supply problems are the perplexing ones, while to the other the demand issue is the important one. To all of those working upon the problems of income determination, the macro-economic equivalent of Marshall's two-edged shears analogy would appear instructive. "Induced" and "Induced-byV: A Note on Terminolpgy. Often in reading the technical literature on multiplier analysis and on project appraisal, one encounters the terms ”induced" multipliers and impacts "induced-by" purchases of inputs. One should note very carefully the context within which the terms are being used, for they refer to two vastly different concepts. "Induced-by" impacts are those which result from the purchase of inputs by producers who realize an increase in output due to a public project. The "induced-by” analysis traces the increased purchases of fertilizer and other inputs caused by the completion of an irrigation project, for example. "Induced" multiplier ef- fects, on the otherhand, are those purchases which occur through re-spending of household incomes. The Keynesian multiplier is an induced multiplier. It includes only those spending effects which occur through the household sector. Some multipliers include both an ”induced” com- ponent and an "induced-by" component. An example is the 70 Type II input-output multiplier discussed in a following section of this chapter. Henceforth in this study, when reference is made to the multiplier impacts of household re-spending, these effects will be referred to as Keynesian induced effects. The effects of input purchases will be referred to by the hyphenated term induced-by effects. The Economic Base Multiplier The economic base multiplier, or "export" base multi- plier as it is sometimes called, is the most simple and straightforward of all the regional multipliers.17 The simple economic base multiplier consists of nothing more than the ratio of total employment or income in the region to "basic" employment or income, where "basic" refers to those activities which serve export markets. This state- ment alone is sufficient to point up the implicit assump- tion in economic base analysis that exports constitute the prime mover of the local economy. Thus, changes in the ”export base" are seen to have certain stimulating effects upon employment and income in secondary and tertiary activi- ties; if the basic/non-basic ratio is stable over time and over stages of development, then the effects of changes in the export base upon the rest of the regional economy can be predicted using the economic base multiplier.18 The economic base multiplier has some real advantages over the Keynesian multiplier in regional analysis. Where- as the simple Keynesian multiplier makes no distinction 71 between the propensity to consume locally-produced goods and services and the propensity to import out Of local in- come, the economic base multiplier does. This relationship is implicit in the basic-non-basic distinction. Tiebout demonstrates this by showing that the propensity to consume locally, multiplied by the income created per dollar of local sales, yields a product equal to the ratio of non- basic/total income.19 The simple economic base multiplier discussed above has been described as a short run multiplier because of the absence of consideration of investment expenditures. The long run multiplier can be constructed by simply add- ing a local investment component to the short run multiplier. Thus, the long run multiplier becomes the reciprocal of one minus the sum of the products of the propensity to consume locally times the income created per dollar of local con- sumption sales, and the propensity to invest locally times the income created per dollar of local investment sales, or 1 or OY 1-(PCL 6‘s + PIL OT) As a result of the inclusion of local investment, the long run multiplier will always be greater than the short run multiplier. The extent to which it is greater will depend, of course, upon both the propensity to invest locally and the income created per dollar of local invest- ment . 72 Tiebout defines the "long run" as greater than two years. While some might challenge the arbitrariness of this distinction, for purposes of evaluating the secondary impacts of long-range investments such as those of the Federal water resource program, the Tiebout definition of the long run creates no difficulties. Such investments so greatly exceed the time horizons discussed by Tiebout that one has few qualms about accepting the long run multiplier as the relevant (me for water resource project evaluation. The problem, however, is that the data requirements in- crease greatly when the investment component is added. Thus, most use only the simple multiplier. The economic base approach is basically a comparative statics approach, though (according to Isard)20 Tiebout maintains that it is a dynamic technique. Thus, even though one might do a base study of the same community at two points in time, he would simply have two snapshots of the local economy rather than one. Therefore, it would appear, the greatest uses of the base study are for description. The prediction component of the base study lies largely in the economic base multiplier. The normal pro- cedure in predicting future changes in the local economy is to determine first the ratio of basic to non-basic em- ployment and/or income. Secondly, the future growth in basic or export employment and/or income is somehow estab- lished. Then utilizing the multiplier developed from the current basic-non-basic economic components, the future 73 changes in non-basic employment and/or income are predicted from the expected changes in the basic. It is a fairly simple and straightforward procedure. In using the economic base approach for predictive purposes, as one would be doing if he used the multiplier in an attempt to estimate secondary benefits, the analyst should understand the weaknesses of the technique. Among these are the implicit assumptions that "export" (basic) activities are the prime mover of the local economy and that the relationship between the basic and non-basic sectors of the economy are stable over time. Isard,21 Andrews22 and others have pointed out that substantial evidence exists indicating the relationship is not stable; thus, the predictive powers of the technique are cast in doubt. Barkley and Allison classify economic base analysis as "a somewhat undisciplined body of economic theory" for its failure to satisfactorily interpret the meaning of the basic/non-basic ratio and establish logically the 23 It has been widely argued that ex- causation involved. ports do not constitute the sole "basic" activity of an economy and that, as a result, the "export base" multiplier 24 Whether does not include all of the relevant components. this explains part of the observed instability in the multi- plier over time has not been answered. Another major consideration regarding the use Of the economic base multiplier is the degree of aggregation in- volved. The economic base multiplier, like the Keynesian 74 multiplier, is an "average" multiplier. That is, it aver- ages together the separate multiplier effects of all "basic" industries into a single multiplier, while the multipliers relevant to the individual industries might vary widely. As a result, the multiplier when applied to any change in the basic sector other than one having an identical in- dustrial mix to the current one, will be inappropriate.25 In addition, the less diversified the mix of the change, the less appropriate the multiplier would be, in all probability. Thus, the changes in basic employment, such as that stimulated by a water resource project which at- tracted one firm or group of similar firms, would be amena- ble to analysis using the economic base multiplier only under very unusual circumstances. Barkley and Allison interpret from a passage in Senate Document 97 a charge to the water resource agencies to do economic base analyses as a part of the project plan- ning and evaluation process. They indicate a similar inter- pretation on the part of N. A. Back of the Corps of Engi- neers. Thus, they argue, there is a provision in the water resource development process for economic base studies. Economic base analysis has been widely used as a technique for projecting future "demands" or "requirements" for economic goods. The initial presentation by Homer Hoyt cast base analysis in just such a role in estimating future 26 demand for housing. It has been picked up and used fairly extensively by the water resource agencies in 75 projecting future "requirements" for water or for water re- 27 Normally, the procedure involved is to lated goods. project the growth in non-basic activity, after making some assumptions about changes in basic activity, assuming that water or the water-related goods will be available.28 Then, having established the ”potential" growth with ade- quate supplies of water, the actual water requirements for such a level of output are estimated, over and above those which would actually be available in the absence of public provision of additional supplies. The excess then becomes the "requirements" to sustain the "anticipated" growth. Often the analyst credits the difference in re- gional income to the provision of that water. In effect, such a procedure constitutes a one-factor theory of eco- nomic growth. The procedure described above is quite similar to "approach No. l" to secondary benefit evaluation suggested in the June 1969 Report of the Special Task Force of the Water Resource Council. The suggested approach would have the analyst "Establish an achievable level of National in- come secondary benefits . . ." Then, a "general develop- ment plan" including the "required" public and private in- vestments should be established. Lastly, the contributions of the "specific water resource projects" should be deter- mined and allocated to each project according to relative 29 investment costs. The problem comes, of course, in determining the contribution (i.e., the marginal product) 76 of the water service. However, any approach which did not credit all of the increase in income to the provision of the water service would constitute an improvement over the "one-factor theory." The Bureau of Reclamation has used economic base analysis in a restrospective attempt to determine the secondary income producing effects of irrigation projects.30 These attempts, however, were undertaken more in the spirit of the comparative projection approach (discussed below) than the traditional economic base multiplier approach in that they were directed largely at determining the second- ary effects of previous projects as a guide in predicting the effects of future projects. In this case, not only the inter-temporal stability of the basic/non-basic ratio is subject to question but also the inter-area stability.31 Thus, unless there is some universal, natural and immutable basic/non-basic ratio, such an approach has all of the pit- falls of the comparative projection approach. In the study by Christensen and Matson,33 which uses the economic base concept to modify a statewide multiplier for use in local impact analysis, an attempt was made to evaluate the secondary effects of irrigation develOpment. The induced effects of an increase in irrigated agriculture were estimated based on the assumption that agriculture was a basic industry to the area. Changes in income in the "non-basic" sectors were estimated using the modified state- wide multiplier. However, the estimates of the income fin . yiA\ A 3K 7. < ‘A . If; ...\ 77 changes were accepted as the relevant secondary benefits without any consideration being given to the supply con- ditions or the opportunity costs of the basic income re- ceiving units in the analysis. The assumption was im- plicitly made that intensive income growth would occur to owners of retail and service establishments due to the fuller utilization of underemployed facilities, while at the same time extensive growth would occur through the development of other similar facilities. At no point was it established (even by explicit assumption) that such facilities were currently under-utilized. Neither was it established as to whether extensive employment growth would come from employment of previously unemployed local people or from immigration. (Neither was it established as to whether there were unemployed local people). Each of these are necessary for one to determine whether the esti- mated impacts are the real monetary changes in the welfare of the people involved. In summary, though economic base studies have been used widely in the water resource develOpment field, there .is some question as to their applicability to secondary benefit evaluation. A most basic question is that regard- ing the stability of the multiplier, not to mention the 3kick of a theoretical basis for its importance. Though it. deals with the problem of local versus non-local con- SUantion which limits the Keynesian multiplier, it has all Of the problems of the Keynesian multiplier in terms of 78 aggregation. In addition, as in the case of the Keynesian multiplier, the economic base approach does not allow the analyst to determine the real net changes in welfare of the people involved. The units which are typically used in the economic base multiplier are employment, income, and/or Value added, or some similar measure. The crude estimates of tlie changes does not give much insight into the basic quest:ion of "How much better off are the people involved?" (i.e.,, the people already in the region). If the changes in t}1ese measures occur through extensive growth (i.e., a changge in the number of jobs without a change in the kinds 0f jcabs or in average wages) rather than intensive growth in tlle region, it is quite possible that no one individual woulcl be any better off, though both regional income and emplrbyment could have grown substantially.32 In the case 0funder-employment, one is specifically interested in inteulsive growth (i.e., changes in the composition of emplxoyment and the level of average wages). IES_J;pmparative Projection Approach The comparative projection approach has been much m01¥3 widely practiced than the discussions of it, per se, inthe economics literature would indicate. The comparative prc’liection concept is a fairly simple one, though the téCihnique itself sometimes becomes a bit involved, and (then even confused. As its title indicates, the approach utllizes comparative analyses of similar areas -- one (U rfl 79 (group) having a public project, the other not -- in an attempt to estimate the differences in income which re- bound to the advantage of the project region. The approach represents an attempt to apply the "controlled experiment” approach Of scientific investigation, the "without-project" group in this case representing the ”control group." The differences which exist in the parameters deemed to be im- portant are noted. If a systematic pattern exists concern- ing the differences, and if that pattern can not be logic- ally explained by some other "uncontrolled variable," the cause of the difference is assigned to the existence of the public projects. Usually the analyst computes a "multiplier" which consists of the ratio of the project area/non-project area income, employment or whatever parameter or index of parameters one desired to use. Though not the first use of such an approach, the presentation of the formalized version of the comparative projection model can be attributed to John E. Pearson. Pearson attempted to develop and present "a theoretical model which would predict with reasonable accuracy the economic impact of water impOundment on the surrounding 34 A simulation approach was used in which an at- areas." tempt was made to simulate the economic growth process of two water impoundment areas, using a third area which did not have a water impoundment as a check on the model. Economic parameters felt to be of economic significance, and for which data were commonly obtainable, were selected 80 for inclusion in the model. These included area population, area income, area agricultural income, and distance to a metropolitan area. Exogenous factors expected to impact on the local economy were project construction expenditures, project operation and maintenance expenditures, project- related associated investments, and visitor recreation ex- penditures. A model designed to simulate the economic growth generated by these exogenous factors and composed of the above economic parameters was described. Pearson says that ”The model en toto provides a trans- formation of valid macro-economic theory into a workable "35 However, he does simulator of a micro-economic system. not demonstrate this fact to the reader. Indeed, there is no theoretical foundation laid in either macro-economic or micro-economic terms, though there is implicit in his equations some basic "theory" about how income growth occurs (for instance, the exponential growth equations of pp. 34- 42). A similar criticism can be made for other comparative projection techniques. While one must admit that no readily acceptable theory of economic growth exists at present, this admission should not negate the importance of a theoretical basis for growth projection. Admittedly, one can learn a great deal about the process of growth by the case study approach. However, most comparative pro- jection approachs do not "study" the process, but rather perform a multiplier or rate of growth "transplant" upon 81 another case. At the least, such a process should be ac- companied by a detailed explanation of the similarities between the areas and the reasons the analyst would expect the area in question to grow in a similar manner to the studied area. A similar study to that performed by Pearson was undertaken by the Business Research Center of the Oklahoma City University. However, rather than attempting to simu- late the growth process, the Oklahoma study simply used linear regression techniques to estimate growth rates in income, etc., from time series data. The rate of growth which had been realized by Oklahoma areas having impound- ments was estimated from time series data and used as the "with-project" case in analyzing the economic impact of the Hugo Reservoir. The pre-project rate of growth of the Hugo Reservoir area was used as the "without-project" case. The difference was purportedly attributable to the presence of reservoirs.36 The Bureau of Reclamation has undertaken at least three such studies of their project areas in an attempt to estimate the secondary impact of irrigation projects. The studies by Marts, and Struthers were retrospective analyses of irrigation development projects, much in the spirit of the above-discussed studies. The objective in these studies was also to determine the relationship between water pro- jects and economic growth. r9 1' .) ShOL ties anal is a cuss the 82 A common failure of all of the comparative projection techniques which have been discussed has been the failure to develop a prOper thread of logic linking the availability of water or a water service to the process of economic growth. Perhaps the milieu in which the reports were written or the audience to which they were directed can explain this failure. It is understandable that the avail- ability of water in a water deficit area such as the western United States might be accepted axiomatically as a (if not ppe) determinant of economic growth. Nevertheless, a great deal of credibility is lost on the uninitiated as result of the lack of an established link. Lacking a water- related growth theory, the advocate of such an approach should as a second-best alternative describe the similari- ties between the areas which might justify the comparative analysis. In the case of "multiplier transplants," which is a form of comparative analysis, the analyst should dis- cuss in detail the factors which influence the level of the particular multiplier and should give his reasons for believing these factors -- and, thus, the level of the particular multiplier -- to be similar between the areas. The Corps of Engineers Test Team Study of the Mountain Home Project provides a case in point37 (see Chapter VI). Con- sidering the very great time limitation under which the Team worked, the ”multiplier transplant was perhaps the only means by which regional development effects might be approximated. Nevertheless, under normal project “.1 Ala. 83 appraisal circumstances, a great deal more evidence as to the applicability Of that multiplier should be required of the analyst. One should be quite wary of the comparative projection approach as a means of estimating secondary project impacts. The comparative growth rates are not developed from "con- trolled" experiments, though the analyst might strive very diligently to find comparable areas in which the lack of a project is the only difference. In reality, comparable areas can seldom be found. Thus, the analyst must accept some divergence for his desired control group. The sensi- tivity of the growth rates experienced under different industry mixes to certain kinds of public investments has not been established. The effects of different size com- munities and the resultant differences in scale economies might negate the supposed correction for population dif- ferences -- i.e., the use of per capita income, etc. Similar precautions apply to the use of "transplanted multipliers." Differences in industrial mix and structure and in local consumption and investment propensities can cause income multipliers from seemingly similar areas to differ considerably. The amount by which they might differ could be partially checked through the use of Bromley's index of internal purchases discussed below. However, where analytical alternatives are possible such ”trans- plants" should be avoided. 84 Index of Internal Purchases Bromley argues that, when one considers the Oppor- tunity costs Of the technical manpower involved, input- output analysis has been overdone in recent years. He main- tains that, for most of the purposes for which local busi- ness income multipliers are used, acceptable local multi- pliers can be generated at a much lower cost than by con- structing input-output models. Thus, he argues for the adoption of the "index of internal purchases" approach where the analyst-planner desires a ranking of relative multipliers between sectors rather than necessarily the absolute magnitude Of those multipliers. He demonstrates that, in eight cases for which input-output multipliers could be compared, the relative rankings of sector multi- pliers yielded by the index of internal purchases are identical to those yielded by the input-output tables.38 Very simply stated, the Bromley approach would arrange the sectors into a four quandrant format according to the proportions of their purchases and sales which are local. Those sectors for which the proportions are high for both purchases and sales would be placed in quadrant I; in quadrant II would be those sectors which bought from sectors in quadrants IV and I and used them in producing items for export; the quadrant III sectors would be those which import much of their inputs and export most of their ‘39“. ALL; 85 output; quadrant IV sectors would be those which bought little locally yet sold a great deal locally.39 Bromley maintains that such a breakdown is sufficient for most community development planners, since what they really need to know is for which sectors they should pro- mote growth to achieve the greatest secondary effect upon local business. For their purposes, the actual size of those multipliers is only of secondary importance for in- ternal planning purposes. While the index of internal purchases might be suf- ficient for many local planning purposes, it constitutes a very imprecise means for estimating secondary benefits. The index yields an ordinal measure of sector impacts which can be useful to the local planner. However, for compari- sons between localities Or between projects justified largely by primary benefits and those seeking justifica- tion based upon their secondary impacts, the index is not quite so helpful. Thus, it is doubtful that the approach, as it now stands, could serve alone as a means for estima- ting secondary benefits. However, it is quite possible that the index could be of use as a check upon other ap- proaches, such as the more aggregative multipliers dis- cussed above, in estimating whether the actual sectors impacted might have multipliers greater than or less than the aggregate multiplier used. Such a procedure might, at best, allow for an adjustment upward or downward of the aggregate multiplier to reflect those differences. ’t‘i 86 From-to Analysis From-to analysis is one approach in an increasingly pOpular area of economic analysis known as "inter-industry economics." From-to analysis differs only slightly from input-output analysis, the difference lying chiefly in the form and extent of data collection. Whereas in the typical regional input-output study data are collected regarding both purchases and sales by each sector, in the from-to study only sales by each sector are recorded. The result is a much less costly data collection process in the from-to study. However, a valuable means of cross-checking is lost in the from-to approach. 40 have argued that for many problems Kalter and others in regional analysis, a model which followed output flows alone would be sufficient. For firms in the region selling to other firms in the region, the from-to approach would provide information on the internally produced (regionally) inputs for the latter and the internal sales of the former. Thus, for a completely closed region (i.e., a region doing no trading with the outside world), the from-to formulation would yield basically the same information as the input- output approach when all of the inter-firm purchase data were brought together. Obviously, the from-to formulation ignores imports, since sales from extra-regional firms are not included in the data collection process. If one were interested only in the intra-regional effects of certain impacts, this In (I? 87 exclusion would be of little importance. A more important disadvantage for regional analysis purposes is the fact that such a data collection process does not allow one to estimate the value added coefficients for the producing sectors. Thus, what is actually developed, if no further additions are made to the basic data, is a matrix of intra- regional requirements for the production of the total sector outputs of the region. The from-to approach is capable of most of the ana- lytical uses to which input-output analysis can be put. The most obvious exceptions, of course, are those concern- ing inter-regional trade analysis, since the from-to formulation does not include imports from other regions. Most of the multipliers which can be derived from input- output studies and which are relevant to secondary benefit evaluation can be computed from the from-to study, if an additional data collection effort is undertaken to provide the value added components for each sector. Thus, the dis- cussion of these will be saved for the section on input- output analysis. Additionally, many of the assumptions and limitations of from-to analysis are common to input- output analysis as well and will be reserved for discussion in that section. Because from-to analysis includes only locally- purchased inputs, the analyst assumes implicitly when utilizing the model for projection that inter-regional trade patterns will remain stable over time and as regional 88 output changes. Since multiplier analysis is inherently a projection technique, one should be aware of the trade stability assumption in evaluating secondary benefits utilizing multipliers derived from such studies. If a principal impact of the project under study were to stimu- late import-substituting industries, the typical from-to formulation would not allow one to measure the local second- ary effects. Jansma and Back41 used the from-to formulation in estimating the local secondary impacts of small watershed projects. The most unusual aspect of the study was the method used in acquiring sales data. Microfilmed records of checks which were cleared through the only bank in the community were the basic source of data. Since information was contained concerning both the payer and the payee, a matrix could be constructed which included not only in- ternal transactions but also imports and exports. The difficulty, however, was that for small owner-operated businesses, for some professionals and for farms, informa- tion on household consumption were inseparable from business inPut purchases. Thus, only induced multipliers could be constructed, since some household sector expenditures were implicitly endogenous. As a result, information regarding inPUt requirements and inter-industry linkages was somewhat Obscured. In the previously mentioned studies by Kalter, on the other hand, such a problem was not encountered, Since firm-by-firm surveys were taken. However, the Cit Gr: 7-3 89 survey method used by Kalter would require a household survey, as well as the firm surveys, to provide the informa- tion implicit in the approach used by Jansma and Back. Input-Output Analysis 1n the input-output model has been called a static general equilibrium model which depicts the inter-industry and inter-market flows of goods and services at a given point in time.42 Though some have questioned the "general equilibrium" aspects of the above characterization, there is general agreement that the input-output technique is a comparative statics analysis.43 That is, the inter- industry transactions matrix which is basic to input-output analysis is analogous to a "snapshot" of the economy at a single point in time. The basic unit of the input-output model is the transactions matrix or table. The rows of the table de- scribe the sales by each industrial sector to other in- dustrial sectors and to final demand; while the columns detail the purchases by each industrial sector from other industrial sectors (and from other regions, if the model is "open") . From the transactions matrix, two other matrices are generated in most input-output studies. The direct re- quirements matrix gives the breakdown of each dollar of gross Output by each sector and describes its flows to other sectors for inputs and to value added. The procedure 1" ... u-y. v». tll £11 4,, 'CA‘ ;": 1., IEL‘ 90 involved is to simply divide the elements in each column of the transactions matrix by the adjusted gross output for that industry.44 The third matrix is the direct and in- direct requirements matrix, which describes the input re- quirements, both direct and indirect, which result from each dollar of gross output by each sector. The direct and indirect requirements matrix considers the derived demands which result from a change in the final demand for the output of one sector and the second and ensuing rounds of demands which are derived from the demands for the inputs used to produce the output to meet that change in final demand. In most cases, when both the direct and indirect effects have worked themselves out, the output requirements imposed upon the sector experiencing the change in final demand will exceed that of the final demand change alone. This is due to the fact that additional outputs of that sector will be required as inputs into other sectors which supply inputs to the former sector (or perhaps to other sectors which do so). Thus, obviously, the coefficients in the cells of the direct and indirect requirements table will be larger than those of the direct requirements table. The direct and indirect requirements matrix can be computed from the direct requirements matrix. One method of computation would be to simply multiply through the round after round effects of one sector on another. Since the round-by-round effects become successively smaller, o '- n\ «\b .1 .‘~ . is \u.\ .\s 91 probably eight to ten such computations would yield a fairly close approximation to the "infinite series" sum. In some cases, such a round by round procedure is used -- generally because the analyst feels that the infinite series sum is inappropriate for some reason or another and that he 45 How- should "truncate" the expansions after a few rounds. ever, in the general case, the full measure of the expan- sionary effects is computed in which case the round-by- round method wOuld become a bit laborious, especially for some of the larger matrices. By inverting the "leontief Matrix," one can achieve the same results as by multiply- ing through all of the round effects. This was the basic eclectic contribution of Wassily Leontief,46 the applica- tion of matrix techniques to the analysis of interindustry flows. The Leontief matrix is defined in matrix notation as [I-A], where A is the direct requirements matrix and I is an identity matrix of the same dimensions. The input-output model is composed of a system of linear equations. As stated above, the equations depict in snapshot fashion the interindustry flows of goods and services at a particular point in time. Thus, while the input-output model provides a very detailed view of the current structure of inter-industry flows, when used for projection purposes it has all of the problems which attend the use of a static model for such purposes. For instance, the direct requirements coefficients reflect the average rather than marginal relationships between inputs and 92 outputs. Thus, in using the model to project input re- quirements for higher levels of output one assumes im- plicitly that the marginal relationships are equal to the average. This amounts to imputing a linear homogeneity to the production functions involved. Further, since the pro- portions between the inputs used and the outputs of each sector are fixed in the model, it is implicitly assumed that no input substitution will occur in any of the pro- duction procesSes. Stated another way, if used for pro- jecting, the model assumes that the supply functions for all factors are infinitely elastic at the prevailing prices. Thus, one of the ”frictions" which the projection version assumes away is that of factor supply inelasticities, in- cluding any market imperfections which might contribute to those inelasticities. While a real descriptive strength of the model is its ability to show explicitly the interde- pendencies between industries, this same explicit statement of interdependence allows the following seemingly-logical interpretation of sectoral importance: Since the outputs of some sector (e.g., the paper clip industry) are used either directly or indirectly in fixed proportions with other inputs by all other sectors in the matrix, a shortage or a blockage in the supply of paper clips would force the halting of all industrial production. Of course, this is absurd. Nevertheless, a strictly-interpreted logical extreme is that such would be the case. Thus, the 93 fundamental economic principle of input substitution is ig- nored by gross application of the input-output model. While the input-output model obviously has its weak- nesses, it is still the most powerful of the regional models. No other approach allows one to deal with regional economic impacts at such a disaggregated level. Though the literature on input-output analysis abounds with dis- cussions of "the aggregation problem," the aggregation in- volved in input-output analysis is very slight in compari- son to that of the economic base model or the Keynesian model. Thus, input-output analysis allows a great deal more specificity on the part of the analyst in estimating the extent and the incidence of secondary economic impacts on a local community. The disaggregation in the input- output model allows one to compute many multipliers rather than a single "average" multiplier. Multipliers for each industrial sector can be computed. Thus, if the incidence of the impact is known, the multiplier effects can be esti- mated with much more precision than is possible with the more aggregative (and, hence, much less costly to construct) multipliers such as those from the economic base model. As pointed out above, the input-output model allows one to construct a number of multipliers. Thus, the term "the multiplier” is not even singularly applicable to input-output multipliers. Some of the most widely used input-output multipliers are discussed below and their 94 advantages and disadvantages for secondary benefit estima- tion are noted. Output Multipliers The simplest of all input-output multipliers to com- pute are the "output multipliers.” These simply show the direct and indirect changes in gross output stimulated by a $1.00 change in demand for each industrial sector. Thus, the output multiplier for a particular sector is merely the sum of the entries in the vector of "direct and indirect requirement per dollar of sales" for the industry in ques- tion. Output multipliers can be instructive as to the "activity" stimulated by a particular policy, where activity refers to gross economic output. If one were interested, for some reason, in maximizing the level of economic ac- tivity generated by a given volume of exogenous impact, the output multipliers would serve as a useful guide to the choice of sectors towards which the emphasis should be directed. However, one is more often interested in the income-producing effects of a policy rather than the stimu- lation of gross activity. Thus, while output multipliers can yield valuable information as to relative sectoral interpedence, they can be misleading when used to estimate income effects. In general, the larger the volume of input purchases from other sectors per dollar of sales, the larger will be 95 the output multiplier for a particular sector. At the same time, however, the volume of such purchases is inversely related to the value added coefficient for the sector in question. Thus, the use of output multipliers as a guide in determining which industrial sectors to emphasize in a community development plan leads one to adopt a development strategy which is perhaps diametrically opposite to what many would consider the "proper" strategy, since the sectors having the lowest value added per dollar of sales tend to be those having the greatest sectoral interdependence. Unless the agglomerative attractions of the sector empha- sized are great, such a policy can lead to a predominance of low-wage (or low employment) and perhaps low-profit in- dustries in the area. Obviously, few local communities would desire to adopt such a strategy. Yet, in their input-output study of the Oklahoma economy, Doeksen and Little47 advised that, since the output multipliers for "agricultural processing" and "livestock and livestock products" were relatively large, those sectors should be emphasized for development purposes. While the relative size of the output multiplier is inversely related to the direct income (i.e., value added) of a sector, it is perhaps positively related to the in- direct income produced by that sector. Since relatively larger volumes of activity are stimulated by sectors having large output multipliers, the possibility of second- ary net income stimulation occurring is much greater for 96 these sectors, also. However, the income secondarily stimu- lated also depends largely upon the income-producing capa- city of the linked industries. Thus, the output multipliers can not be accepted as dependable guides to the secondary income-producing capacity of a sector, though there perhaps exists some degree of correlation between the two. For such purposes, one is best advised to use one of the income multipliers discussed below. For secondary benefit evaluation purposes, one is more likely to be interested in income than in "activity generation." Thus, output multipliers are not likely to be particularly helpful. Additionally, since in secondary benefit evaluation one is likely to be dealing with economically-depressed localities, output multipliers can create a dangerous bias towards perpetuating a poor in- dustrial mix for the locality. This is true because of the tendency for from-to models and regional input-output models to identify the strongest intra-regional linkage effects in the structural matrix. The problem comes in situations in which the regional industrial mix includes a pre- dominance of slow-growing industries.48 The regional interindustry model shows the greatest interdependence effects, obviously, for those industries which are "estab- lished" in the area. Thus, the output multipliers will be greater for those sectors which are linked to the (slow growing) sectors which are already there. At least when the income multiplier is used instead of the output “In; E.— 11M Fe 97 multiplier, those sectors which pay low wages (or employ few people) are penalized in the relative size of their interdependence effects. The output multiplier includes no such penalty. Type I (direct-indirect) Income Multipliers A better guide to the income-increasing effects of sectoral interdependence than that provided by output multi- pliers is that given by the direct-indirect income multi- pliers. The basic difference between the two is the em- phasis of the latter upon income stimulation rather than activity generation. While the output multiplier shows the direct and indirect activity generated per dollar of sales for the sector, the direct-indirect income multiplier depicts the direct and indirect income changes in compari- son to the direct income changes. The multiplier which results is the ratio of direct plus indirect income to direct income alone.49 The direct-indirect income multiplier was developed from an input-output study of the St. Louis Metropolitan area by Werner Hirsch.50 In that same study, Hirsch pre- sented a second income multiplier which included, in ad- dition to the direct and indirect income changes, an "induced" component. The induced component incorporated the effects of re-spending by households into the multiplier effect, which the direct-indirect income multiplier ex- cluded. Hirsch called these multipliers "Type I" and It ~ It \ at} E ;h\ Fly. 1 5“ \u. I n\. . ‘l « N. .. shun C r . .l‘ W ,P. a » TE 98 Type II” multipliers, the Type 11 being the multiplier which included the induced income component. The Type II multipliers will be discussed later in a following section. To derive the direct-indirect (Type I) multipliers two matrixes are needed: First, the direct requirements matrix with households included in the structural matrix is needed. In other words, a row must be added to the transactions matrix to show the wages, salaries and profits per dollar of direct sales, and a column must be added which shows the purchases by households from every other sector and from households (the sums of the column and the row entries must be equal). Secondly, the matrix of direct and indirect requirements per dollar of sales (with house- holds outside of the structural matrix) is needed. To estimate the direct-indirect income multipliers for a sector (call it sector A), one would multiply the elements in the sector A column of the direct and indirect require- ments matrix by the household row of the direct require- ments matrix and sum the products (i.e., using matrix pro- cedures, post-multiply the household row of the direct requirements matrix by the "A" column of the direct and indirect requirements matrix); then divide the sum of the 51 The products by the sector A entry in the household row. result is the Type I income multiplier for sector A. It expresses the relationship between direct and indirect income changes due to sectoral interdependence and direct changes in income in sector A. 99 As stated above, if one desires a measure of the relative income-producing sector linkages, the direct- indirect income multipliers provide a much more reliable sector ranking device than do the output multipliers. How- ever, like the output multipliers, the direct-indirect in- come multipliers do not include the feedback effect from household expenditures. Thus, these multipliers only show the buildup in household income which results from the direct and indirect requirements imposed upon other sectors (and itself) by changes in the output of sector A. A point should be made in passing regarding the relevant change to which the direct-indirect income multi- plier should be applied. While the input-output tables of requirements show the input required from other sectors to allow a one dollar change in output (sales) of sector A, the direct-indirect income multipliers show the change in both direct and indirect income which results from a one dollar change in direct income. Thus, in estimating the direct and indirect income effects of a one dollar change in the output of sector A, one should not simply multiply that one dollar change by the above multiplier. One would be applying the multiplier to the gross change in output of sector A rather than to the direct change in income. Thus, the direct-indirect income changes are much smaller than is sometimes erroneously estimated using such multi- pliers. For example, if the household coefficient in Column A were .20 and the sector A multiplier were 2.0, 100 a one dollar change in export sales of sector A would not generate two dollars in income, but, rather, it would generate forty cents in income. The difference comes in how one defines the initial change in direct income. If the dollar initial change is, in fact, the direct income component, then the multiplier should properly be applied to that figure. However, if the dollar is instead an exogenous change in export demand, then for regional analysis purposes the "initial income" aspect of that dollar is realized in another region; and the initial re- gion income is only twenty cents. This differs somewhat from the output multipliers, discussed above, because of the difference in the base. The base of the output multi- pliers is formed by the initial dollar change in demand for the output of that sector. Thus, the output multiplier should normally be applied to that figure. However, if the full income effect of that initial dollar expenditure is not realized in the region, then that dollar should be subtracted from the effects of the output multiplier. This differentiation between the initial income incidences was not considered by Doeksen and Little in their analysis, however, since they were dealing largely with gross activity generation instead of changes in local income, per se. Since the Type I multiplier ignores the effects of the household re-spending (induced) component, it assumes, in effect, that the marginal propensity to consume locally (out of household income) is zero. Thus, if one derived 101 a set of Type II multipliers and added an adjustment for the propensity to consume locally, the Type II multiplier would reduce to the Type I multiplier when the MPCL=O. Such a situation would only exist in the "real world” if the com- munity in question had no retail sector nor other facilities for selling to households, so that all consumer spending occurred outside of the community. For all practical purposes, the only communities which would fit such a mold would be industrial parks or city sectors which were zoned for industrial develOpment only. It is unlikely, however, that an analyst would define such a region as the relevant one for study -- especially in the evaluation of secondary benefits, which should have their basis in real changes in consumer welfare. The process of multiplier analysis is a very pre- carious one wrought with some very great assumptions re- garding economic behavior. The assumptions made in the calculation of the indirect requirements matrix provide a case in point: It is assumed in carrying out those calcu- lations that all of the factors needed for the envisioned expansion (both directly and indirectly) will be available at current prices; further it is assumed that they will be used in the same proportions as depicted in the tables and that no thwarting of the derived demands for them will occur via market imperfections, etc. The net effects of these assumptions, in all probability, is to bias upwards the estimates of the real expansionary effects. If, at 102 the same time, an induced component is added, the resulting projections can greatly exceed the actual multiplier ef- fects. Thus, if one suspects that the "leakages” from the endogenous matrix are greater than those depicted, and he at the same time suspects that the induced effects are over- stated (the reasons this might be so will be discussed in the sector on Type II multipliers which follows), then the rule-of-thumb correction provided by the Type I multiplier might, in fact, make it a better estimate of the actual multiplier effects than the Type II multiplier. Thus, one might choose to use the Type I multiplier as a "more reason- able" estimate of the true secondary impacts under such cir- cumstances. In secondary benefit evaluation, the analyst should attempt to identify the net secondary changes in real in- come which accrue to the relevant unit of analysis (i.e., to the nation or to the region, depending upon which "account" he is dealing with). The output multipliers are better in one respect than are the more aggregative ap- proaches: They allow the analyst to identify the sectors experiencing the greatest gross activity changes and, thus, can help point out the sectors in which supply conditions can be most critical. However, they are weaker in two respects: First, they incorporate the gross output con- cept rather than income; and, second, they do not include the induced component of income growth. The Type I multi- pliers, on the other hand, go one step further than the 103 output multiplier in that they utilize the income effects as the relevant multiplier effects rather than gross output. However, they do not include the induced income growth com- ponent. Thus, their applicability is limited largely to the three following uses: 1) determination of the sectors having the greatest inter-sectoral income linkages (exclud- ing the household re-spending component) for purposes of sector emphasis; 2) situations in which the marginal pro- pensity to consume locally is assumed to be very low; or 3) as a rule-of-thumb adjustment for "frictions" and leak- ages in the structural matrix and for leakages from the induced component. Type II (direct-indirect-induced) Multipliers The Type II multiplier differs from the Type I multi- plier by the addition of the induced component only. The induced component incorporates into the multiplier the expansionary effects of the re-spending by households of incomes earned during the course of the initial and ensuing output expansions. Thus, the household sector is assumed to act in a fashion similar to the producing sectors in the structural matrix -- i.e., it increases its "requirements" as "sales" (household income) expand. 'In recognition of this link between household ex- penditures and household income, Hirsch removed the house- hold sector from the final demand category and placed it in the structural matrix in computing his Type II 104 multipliers. To do so, he had to determine the distribution of expenditures by households to each sector in the struc- tural matrix (including other households); and he had to determine the part of each sales dollar for each sector which went to households in the form of wages, salaries, profits, and interest. Having determined these, Hirsch re-inverted the Leontief matrix with households included in the endogenous matrix. Then, to estimate the multiplier for some sector (Sector A), he took the household coef- ficient for Sector A from this new matrix and divided it by the household coefficient for Sector A from the direct requirements matrix._ The ratio which resulted was the Type II multiplier. While, in concept, the addition of the induced com- ponent offers a more realistic approach to estimating multiplier effects, there are two new problems created by its addition. First, since most regional input-output studies do not include a household survey, the household column has to be estimated outside of the model. Typically, the coefficients from national input-output studies are used in regional studies. Thus, if no adjustments are made, one is forced to assume that inter-regional consumption patterns are invariant. To appreciate the compromise which such an assumption entails one must simply reflect upon the fact that national coefficients will include items con- sumed in one part of the nation which perhaps are not even marketed in the region for which the study is being made -- 105 e.g., alcoholic beverages sales are illegal in many south- ern counties. The fact that homes in Maine incur very sub- stantial heating costs while many Florida homes do not even have central heating can only be rationalized by assuming that the Florida air conditioning costs Offset the difference. If air conditioning and heating implements are produced in the same industrial sector, then the problem is perhaps lessened. Nevertheless, regional coefficients would normally provide better measures of induced multiplier effects in the region than do those borrowed from national tables. Secondly, the addition of the induced component also necessitates the additional assumption that the mix of household purchases remains the same as income increases. The implicit assumption is that the income elasticity of demand of all items in the household budget is equal to unity. Thus, as income increases by 1 per cent, expendi- tures for all items in the household "market basket" in- crease by 1 per cent. This is analogous to the assumptions made concerning the other "producing" sectors in the struc- tural matrix regarding the linear homogeneity of the pro- duction functions involved. However, while there has been an unresolved controversy regarding the fixity of the in- put coefficients, the difficulty posed by the static con- sumption function can be resolved by making one rather palatable additional assumption. That assumption concerns the manner in which income grows as a result of the 106 expansion. If output (and income) increase as a result of extensive growth rather than intensive growth, then the assumption can be made that the consumption patterns of the "new" money earners will be the same as those of the "old" money earners at the same level of income. Thus, if regional output increases as a result of bringing in new workers at approximately the same wages as the resident workers, it would appear reasonable that the ”average” con- sumption patterns would not change very much. However, if income grew as a result of more intensive use of resident workers and average incomes increased as a result, then one should reasonably expect the pattern of consumption to change.52 While the Type II multiplier includes the induced multiplier effects of household spending, it does not allow for the effects of other income-related changes in expendi- tures which will have further expansionary effects upon income. Increases in investment and government expenditures which will occur as a long-run effect have been excluded. Thus, the Type II multiplier is only a short run multiplier. To adjust for the long-run induced effects of these two additional factors one would follow the same procedure as was followed in incorporating the household re-spending into the model. Column and row values for each would have to be estimated, adjusted and placed in the matrix of direct requirements. Then a new Leontief matrix would be computed and inverted with households, investment, and 107 government all in the endogenous matrix with the producing sectors.53 The long-run induced multipliers would be com- puted in the same manner as the short-run induced (Type II), the difference being that the household coefficients \vould be larger as a result of the effects of "capturing" ‘the effects of investment and government spending in the s tructural matrix. The difficulty with the long-run induced multiplier :is that it compounds the already-unrealistic lack of con- ssideration of leakages from the model. The problems posed 11y the assumptions made concerning the "frictions" and ileakages in the input-output model have already been dis- cmissed. Isard54 highlights the problem by pointing out that an input-output model as such contains no restrictions on rates of expansion and contraction and on multiplier effects. The SOphisticated analyst usually allows for such restrictions; typically, he establishes the final demand sectors at such magnitudes tha, being fixed, they auto- matically set reasonable restraints on rates of change and multiplier effects. When, however, the important households sector is removed from the final demand sectors, unrealistic rates of change and multiplier effects do result unless other modifications are made which introduce com- pensating restrictions or leakages. (Inite obviously, the removal of two more sectors from final demand multiplies the problem. The removal of all the final demand sectors would, obviously, lead to an under- identified system of equations.55 The long-run induced multiplier comes very close to creating the latter problem, in that the only factors left to "explain" the level 108 of the system are exports (and exogenous public and private investment in the case of regional analysis, where only As a result, the local governments are made endogenous). long-run induced multiplier is generally an unreliable estimator of the actual long-run multiplier effects.56 Be- cause of the problems caused by leakages, the (short-run) 'Type II multiplier might, in fact, provide a more reliable estimate of the long-run multiplier effects than does the long-run induced multiplier. Input-Output and Secondary Benefits: An Overview Because it allows the most detailed analysis of sectoral interdependence, input-output analysis constitutes the most effective tool the analyst possesses in evaluating Shecondary impacts. The biggest problem in applying the tkschnique is the cost and the time required to construct tile tables. Where input-output studies exist for the im- IPElcted region, however, the opportunities for detailed allalysis of secondary benefits far exceed those Offered 13)’ other techniques. Input-output analysis is not without its problems as 3J1 analytic technique, though its problems are perhaps “Hach less severe than many other regional analysis tech- Iliques. Its greatest weakensses are manifest when it is Ilsed for projection purposes; multiplier analysis is a form of projection. 109 Dorfman points out the problem of time involved in interpreting the matrix of requirements. Since the techno- logical relationships in the matrix refer to the current level of output of each industry, the past level of output of its suppliers, and subsequent levels of output of its customers, input-output analysis" . . . abstracts from the time sequence of production and exchange . . ." and, thus, ". . . applies only to a stationary equilibrium, where time is of no consequence."57 Since the multiplier techniques include the round-after-round expansions as well, the ‘problem of time is compounded. Thus, the multiplier not only abstracts from time in dealing with the direct re- lationships, it also further abstracts from time in han- lier effects might be included where l) the conditions of Sllpply for all factors stimulated to employment by the in- Vestment are perfectly elastic at prevailing prices, 2) tlle opportunity costs of those factors in the absence of tlle investment are zero in all cases -- i.e., the full fFactor price consists of economic rent, and 3) the outputs Wl'lich result do not simply substitute for other products ill the market place; thus they do not unemploy other ffictors of production. Normally these conditions are not 118 present in the general case. Thus, multipliers in general (whether Keynesian multipliers or input-output multipliers) exhibit a consistent tendency to over-estimate the real welfare effects of secondary impacts. That any or all of the above conditions might partially hold in many cases is not questioned. However, the typical approach to multi- plier analysis assumes that all of these conditions hold fully. Thus, the "secondary benefits" which are generally estimated using secondary impact analysis are not really net secondary benefits at all, even from the viewpoint of the factors being employed. Rather, they are gross changes (usually long run) in the demand for those factors. Multiplier analysis is basically a projection techni- que. All of the uses of the multiplier which were discussed above deal with the multiplier as a tool for projecting the expansions in income, employment or economic activity re- sulting from certain exogenous changes. In addition to projecting expansion, input-output multipliers can also be used to prp£e_the incomes received from current or direct output, since the input-output model gives a detailed description of the factor payments in- volved in producing the outputs of a particular industry. The factor payments are based upon market prices which might or might not represent the real opportunity costs of those factors, nor of the resources which might have been used in producing the factors. In those cases in which the factor prices differ from the real opportunity cost, 119 the real value added for that sector will be incorrectly stated. If one knew the real opportunity costs of all factors, the real economic value added by a particular sector could be more accurately estimated. That is, the real shadow price of each output could be estimated by repricing each factor entry at its real opportunity cost and recomputing and inverting the Leontieff matrix (with households outside of the endogenous matrix). The result could be used in either or both of two ways: 1) To project the real income from an expected expansion in out- put due to an expected change in final demand (the estimate would have all of the problems posed by projecting from input-output models discussed above), and/or 2) to estimate the total factor rents (i.e., factor prices minus real opportunity costs) earned by all of the factors and sub- factors used in producing the current output. The latter use would simply constitute a full shadow pricing of the current outputs. The former would constitute a full shadow pricing of expected outputs. 120 Footnotes 1. Kneese, op cit, 24-9. 2. Harvey Leibenstein, "Allocative Efficiency vs. 'x-Efficiency'," The American Economic Review (June 1966), 392-415. 3. Peter Helmberger, "O-Efficiency and the Economic Organization of Agriculture," in Agricultural Organization in the Modern Industrial Economy (Columbus: 1969). 4. See Irma Adelman, Theories of Economic Growth and Development (Stanford: 1961). 5. Glenn L. Johnson, "A Note on Non-Conventional Inputs and Conventional Production Functions," in Agr'- culture in Economic Development, ed. by C. Eicher and L. Witt (New York: 1964). 6. Edwin Kuh, "Unemployment, Production Functions, and Effective Demand," Journal of Political Economy, LXXIV, No. 3, 238-48. 7. Notable exceptions are Ibid; Robert M. Solow, "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function," The Review of Economics and Statistics XXX, 312-20; and Lawrence‘H. Shaw and RObert S. Arden, "Output Effects of a Changing Composition of Industry, 1947-1965," Ihg_ Review of Economics and Statistics XLX, 134-6. 8. Gardner Ackley, Macroeconomic Theory (New York: 1967), 309. 9. Gottfried Haberler, "Mr. Keynes' Theory of the 'Multiplier': A Methodological Criticism," Zeitschrift ffir National 6konomie (1963). 10. Keynes; Op cit, 298. 11. See Abbas Mirokhor and Frank Orazen, "Importance of the Farm Sector to the Economy: A Multiplier Approach," American Journal of Agricultural Economics (November 1968). 12. "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment," Economic Journal (June 1931). 13. The Theory of Inter—sectoral Money Flows and Income Formation (Baltimore: 1950). 121 14. Harry W. Richardson, Elements of Regional Economics (Baltimore: 1969), 23. 15. Robert H. Haveman and John V. Krutilla, Unem- plgyment, Idle Capacity,_and the Evaluation of Public Expenditures: _National_and‘Regi6naI'Analysis (Baltimore: 1968), 28—33. 16. op cit, 914. 17. See Walter Isard, Methods of Rggional Analysis: An Introduction to Regional Science (Cambridge: 1960), I89. 18. Charles M. Tiebout, The Communitnyconomic Base Study, Supplementary Paper Number I6 (nechOfk: December 19. Ibid., 61-2. 20. op cit, 199. 21. 32 cit, 200-1. 22. Richard B. Andrews, "Comment re: Criticisms of the Economic Base Theory," Journal of the American Institute of Planners XX (1958). 23. Paul W. Barkley and Thaine H. Allison, Jr., "Economic Base Studies in Resource Administration," Land Economics XL: 470-9. 24. Hans Blumenfield, "The Economic Base of the MetrOpolis," Journal of the American Institute of Planners XXI (1955). 25. C. L. Leven, "Regional and Interregional Accounts in Perspective," Regional Science Association Papers and Proceeding, XIII: 127F44. 26. See "Homer Hoyt on Development of Economic Base Concept,” Land EconomiC§_(May 1954). 27. See for example Economic Base Survey of the Potomac River Service Area, prepared by the Office of’ Business Economies 0f the U. S. Department of Commerce for the U. S. Army Corps of Engineers (Washington: 1969). 28. Barley and Allison, op cit. 29. Procedures for Evaluation . . . , 107-8. 30. See M. E. Marts, An Experiment in the Measure- ment of the Indirect Benefits of'Irrigation, preparedfor 122 the Bureau of Reclamation, U. S. Department of the Interior, Boise, Idaho (June 1950); and Robert E. Struthers, The Role of Irri ation Development in CommunitygEconomic Structure: Grand Vallpy Trade Area, COlorado (Washington: 1963). 31. Barkley and Allison, op cit. 32. For a more complete discussion of the "intensive" versus "extensive" growth problem, see C. M. Tiebout, "An Empirical Regional Input-Output Projection Model: The State of Washington," Review of Economics and Statistics (August 1969). 33. Impact of Irrigation Development on Income and Trade: Eastern and CentraT'South Dakota (Brookings: February 1969). 34. A Study of the Economic Impact of Water Impound- ment thropgh the Development ofia Comparative Projection Model, Tec nicaI’Report No.*8, water Resources Institute, Texas A and M University (August 1967), 4. 35. Ibid., 42. 36. A Study of the Economic Impact of the Hugo Reservoir on Choctaw andiPushmataha Counties (Oklahoma City: 1969). 37. A Test of Procedures Proposed byya Task Force of the WateriResource Council: Special—Study of ihe Mountain Home Division, Southwest Idaho Water Deveiopment Project, U. S. Army Corps ofiEngineers,CWa11a Walla District (March 1970). 38. "On the Use and Overuse of Input—Output Models: A Methodological Hypothesis," unpublished paper, undated. 39. Ibid., 4-5. 40. R. J. Kalter, Estimating Local Secondary Impacts of Water-Based Recreation Investment USin Interindustry Anal sis (Madison: 1967), andiAn Interin ustry Analysis pf the Central New York Re ion,CBullefin 1025 (Ithaca: 1969); Charies L. Leven, egional Income and Product Accounts: Construction and Applications," in Desi n of Regional Accounts (Baltimore: 1961), Chapter 6; and W. Lee Hansen and Charles M. Tiebout, "In Inter-sectoral Flows Analysis of the California Economy," The Review of Economics Egg Statistics, XLV, No. 4 (November 1963). 41. J. D. Jansma and W. B. Back, Local Secondary; Effects of Watershed Projects: A Case Study_of Roger fins County, OkTalioma (Stilfivater: 1964). 123 42. William H. Miernyk, The Elements of Input- Output Analysis (New York: 1967)} 30} 43. H. H. Stoevener and E. N. Castle, "Input-Output Models and Benefit-Cost Analysis in Water Resources Re- Search," Journal of Farm Economics (November 1965), 1572-9. 44. See Miernyk, op cit, 21. 45. For an example of such a truncation and a dis- cussion of truncated multipliers, see Walter Isard and Robert Kuenne, "The Impact of Steel Upon the Greater New York-Philadelphia Industrial Region," The Review of Eco- nomics and Statistics (November 1953). 46. "Quantitative Input-Output Relations in the Economic System of the United States," The Review of Economics and Statistics (August 1936). 47. Gerald A. Doeksen and Charles H. Little, A2 Analysis of the Structure of Oklahoma's Economy by Districts (Stillwater: 1969). 48. Which also tend to be low-wage, low-value added industries. See Harvey S. Perloff, et a1., Re ions Re- Sources, and Economic Growth (Lincoln: 1960) 63-6. 49. Miernyk, op cit, 47. 50. "Interindustry Relations of a Metropolitan Area," The Review of Economics and Statistics (November 51. See Ibid., and Miernyk, op cit, 42-9. 52. Charles M. Tiebout, "Regional and Interregional Input-Output Models: An Appraisal," Southern Economic Journal XXIV (1957). . 53. For a discussion of long-run versus short-run Input-output multipliers, see Kalter, Estimating_Local §gcondary Impacts . . ., op cit. 54. Isard, Methods of Regional Analysis . . . , 35. 55. Mordecai Ezekial and Karl A. Fox, Methods of Correlation and Regression Analysis: Linear and'Curvi- llnear (New York: 1959), 4IS¥33. . 56. Kalter comes to a similar conclusion. See loc Clt, 77. Ira; ("a lp—ril0w—1 124 S7. "The Nature and Significance of Input-Output," Review of Economics and Statistics (May 1954), 121-33. 58. Ibid., 124. 59. For a discussion of this point, see H. B. Chenery, et al., The Structure and Growth of the Italian Economy (Rome: 1953), T7. 60. Keynes skepticism regarding the mathematical models of some of his colleagues is perhaps relevant to this discussion: "Too large a proportion of recent 'mathematical' economics are mere concoctions, as imprecise as the initial assumptions they rest on, which allow the author to lose sight of the complexities and interdependencies of the real world in a maze of pretentious unhelpful symbols." The General Theory, 298. 61. Dorfman, op cit, 125. 62. Roger Strohbehn, et a1., Analysis of Alternative Procedures for the Evaluation of Agricultural Flood Control Benefits (WaShington: 1971). CHAPTER V ESTIMATING SECONDARY FACTOR INCOME CHANGES Foreword In Chapter II, the literature regarding secondary benefits was reviewed. The survey revealed three classifi- cations of secondary benefits: 1) Customary induced-by and stemming-from effects, 2) externalities and economies of scale, and 3) dynamic secondary benefits. It was concluded that the latter two categories required a great deal of further study and that, at present, they must be approached on a case-by-case basis. Even more so than the customary variety of secondary benefits, the analysis of externali- ties and dynamic effects requires great perception and imagination on the part of the analyst. Only the customary variety of secondary benefits appeared amenable to analysis using currently available economic knowledge and currently available secondary data. In Chapter III, methods of estimating secondary im- pacts were surveyed. The advantages, disadvantages, and assumptions of each were discussed. It was concluded that the major drawbacks to most approaches have been the assumptions of perfect supply elasticity and zero 125 126 opportunity cost of the factors stimulated to employment and the tendency to credit all ensuing changes in the level of income or employment to the initial investment. The latter tendency gives no credit to the associated invest- ments required. It was concluded that the detail provided by the input-output model allowed the analyst the greatest opportunity to adjust for the effects of these factors. It has been maintained throughout the preceding sections of this study that the analyst should apply imagination and reason to the analysis of customary secondary benefits rather than faithfully accepting an estimate of "Th3 Multiplier" as an effective measure of real welfare changes.. The purpose of this section is to demonstrate an alterna- tive approach to such acceptance. The approach utilizes the input-output model as a starting point and incor- porates opportunity cost and economic rent concepts in deriving a set of multipliers which it is believed will more closely represent the real changes in economic welfare which result from the operation of "The Multiplier." The model presented herein is slightly revised from a version used by Schmid and Ward1 in the Michigan State University Test Team report on the Water Resource Council's June 1969 proposed changes in water project evaluation pro- Cedures. The concepts and approaches are essentially the Same. The version presented herein is different from the original in the following respects: 1) The earlier version USead the coefficients from the 1958 input-output study of 127 the United States, while the newer version uses the 1963 coefficients, 2) the assumptions regarding the treatment of profits are changed, 3) the approach to estimating "stemming-from" benefits is changed, and 4) a different procedure for estimating opportunity cost of labor, where the local wage rates are lower than the national wage rates, is used. In addition to demonstrating the application of the revisions in the earlier model, the application of the revised model to the Trenton Channel Project in this Chapter provides a third set of secondary benefit estimates for use in the comparative analysis of the Trenton Channel Project in Chapter VI, which evaluates the sensitivity of secondary benefit concepts to differ- ences in analytical approaches. Estimating Wage Changes Input-output models allow the analyst to trace the impact of a change in final demand through the economy. Since "households" is normally one of the sectors included in the input-output tables, it is possible to estimate the total effects upon household income caused by these final demand changes. As discussed in Chapter III, income multi- pliers derived from input-output studies have generally presumed that all of the income flows to the household sector represent real secondary benefits. As discussed Previously, this convention assumes that the opportunity COSts of the household sector are zero - that is, that all 128 of the wage, salary and profit earners have no valued a1- ternatives. It assumes that all returns on capital in excess of recurrent costs are "pure" profits and ignores the concept of "normal" returns on investment. It under- values leisure and assumes that labor earnings are zero in all possible alternative uses. While this latter assumption might be justified on some grounds in some under- deveIOped countries, it is clearly inappropriate for re- cent conditions in the United States. The Wage Component of Value Added The input-output model provides the analyst with snapshot information relating to average relationships in the economy on a disaggregated basis. It provides much of the information needed to estimate the 3231 changes in income which occur as an indirect result of water resource projects. However, the information in the input-output tables must be supplemented by additional information. Part of this information is currently available in second- ary sources. For example, the household sector (or the value added sector, in some studies) can be disaggregated by using data on wages, profits and sales by industry Which are contained in the "National Income Issues" of the §grvey of Current Business, published by the Department of Commerce. ("The National Income Issue" is normally the July issue.) By dividing the wages and salaries data by the sales for the particular industry, one can obtain a 129 "wages per dollar of sales" coefficient which can be sub- stituted in the direct requirements table. The same is true for profits. Having done this, one could then use the input-output multipliers discussed in Chapter IV to estimate a "wage multiplier" or a "profit multiplier." However, both of these would still deal with the gross con- cepts of wages and profits discussed in the previous para- graph. Though both of these can be useful in their own right, they do not provide appropriate measures of real wage and profit changes (to even the local area) under normal United States conditions. The "wages per dollar of sales" coefficient can further be disaggregated into an "opportunity cost" com- ponent and a "rent" component. The rent component could also be used to generate a "rent multiplier" using the input-output multipliers discussed in Chapter IV. These would show the total net changes in income to workers from a given change in final demand. In order to construct the "rent coefficients," however, one must have information re- garding the alternatives available to the workers in each industry. Unfortunately, there is no generally available source of such information at present, though a slight revision in the application forms used by the State Em- ployment Security Commissions could make such information available on a continuing basis. By requesting the in- dustry of previous employment and the wage rate of each applicant, in addition to the job classification as is now R (I) 130 done, these agencies could provide valuable data required in establishing the alternatives available to the labor force of each industrial sector. It would also improve the estimates of unemployment rates by industry groups. These rates would obviously be even less precise than the currently estimated rates by job classification. Never- theless, they could be of substantial aid in determining which industries could best use an infusion of exogenous demand. More importantly for analytical purposes, this in- formation would allow greater precision in dealing with the problem of supply elasticies, since one could better forecast the emergence of labor shortages for each industry. Even in the absence of data sources regarding alter- native earnings, some logical improvements can be made in the approaches discussed in preceeding chapters. Though it is unlikely that one could establish the precise level of real opportunity costs by logic alone, it is possible to reduce the range of error apparent in traditional ap- proaches. For example, it is apparent that zero is too low an opportunity cost in practically all cases. Any estimate which is higher and can be logically shown to be lower than the actual opportunity cost will narrow the error. Thus, the process becomes one of determining the highest logically defensible estimate. Since "logically defensible" involves a subjective judgement, the estimate should be a conservative one. 131 The most plausible argument relating to alternative labor earnings looks at the bidding process for labor. As the demand for the output of each sector shifts, the derived demand for labor inputs shifts. Under conditions of labor unemployment, the increased demand for labor can be met out of the pool of unemployed resources. When the pool is exhaused, however, firms begin to bid workers away from other firms to meet continued increases in the demand for their products. The firms which give up workers do so by either 1) decreasing their output, or 2) adopting labor- saving technologies. One might assume that those which underwent contractions were "marginal" firms which were earning very low profits (or perhaps were realizing capital losses). These firms were probably (though notnecessarily) among the lowest wage firms in the sector. Thus, one would expect the workers who shifted from the contracting firms to the eXpanding firms to realize some increment of wage improvement, though the difference would not be entirely in the form of real "rent,” since there would be costs associated with the shift. In the case of laborers released by labor-saving technologies, the process is somewhat different. Their former employers are probably not "marginal" firms. If they were, the owners would be unwilling to undertake the capitalization necessary to switch from a high variable- low fixed cost technology to the high fixed cost technology suggested by the process of capital substitution. Thus, 132 one should not surmise that these firms are among the lower wage firms. On the other hand, it is probable that those workers being released are not the firms' highest salaried production workers. The process of capital substitution usually proceeds through the jobs having the lowest skill requirements. Thus, it is probable that the average wage of the workers released is lower than the average wage of all production workers in the firm. Whether it is lower than the average of all production workers in the industry is an empirical question. There is reason to believe that the increased capitalization would occur in the higher profit firms which also tend to pay higher wages. This would at least partially offset any tendency of capital to substitute for lower wage production jobs. In the absence of an extensive and detailed study of this question, it is perhaps most defensible to simply assume that the two more or less offset each other and that the labor released by capital substitution realized little or no transfer rent, even when demand for labor is increasing. Thus, the only rents realized occur through the process of shifting from marginal to expanding firms. Wage rates within the "marginal" firms differ from industry to industry. They normally differ by more than do the wage rates between marginal and expanding firms within the same industrial sector. These differences are largely due to differing capital-labor ratios and skilled-unskilled labor ratios between the different production processes. 133 While some inter-industry labor transfers can and do occur under conditions of increasing demand for labor, the dif- fering labor skill mixes provide some limit to these transfers. Inter-industry transfers normally occur within individual job classifications. Wage differences within the classifications are normally much smaller than the differences between classifications, especially in union- scale trades. Thus, the rents realized by a Worker shift- ing from one industry to another are much smaller than the difference between the average wages for all production workers in the two industries would suggest, since the worker is likely to remain in the same trade. In the absence of data regarding the shift patterns of labor, one alternative is to use the average wage from the sector having the lowest average wages in establishing the alternative costs of labor. In view of the large inter- industry wage differentials highlighted above, this con- vention would appear to greatly understate the real op- portunity cost of the laborers who change jobs. The skills of most of the workers will greatly exceed the average level found in the lowest wage sector. However, this apparent understatement is ameliorated by the "syphon-like" process through which the labor market operates: as one worker moves to higher employment, he is replaced by a second worker of (marginally) lower skill, who is replaced by a third whose skill is (marginally) lower than the second. This process continues until all of the positions 134 are filled or until the limit of the labor supply is reached. The net effect of the process is to increase the sum of the earnings of all involved in the "syphon" by the difference between the new job at the top and the alterna- tive earnings of the last worker affected. Under condi- tions of unemployment, the last worker syphoned up would come from the unemployed; the net results would be the wages of the new job minus the cost of unemployment. Under conditions of "full" employment, the alternative at the bottom of the syphon would be some wage paying job. The convention adopted here is to assume that the alternative is employment as an "average" production worker in the lowest wage industry. This constitutes a very conservative evaluation of the average opportunity costs, since it assumes that the syphoning effect will go all the way to the bottom of the currently employed labor force for every worker affected by the exogenous impact. The Wage Rent Coefficient If one accepts the assumptions outlined above regard- ing labor opportunity costs, a "wage rent coefficient" for use in developing a vector of "wage rent multipliers" can be developed from secondary sources. The data needed are Ci = total labor compensation in each industry (i) Li = total employment in industry i Cs = total labor compensation in lowest average wage industry, where average wage is defined as Ci/Li 5X I I: «\h t» ti< 135 Ls total employment in lowest wage industry Si total value of sales in industry i The "wage rent coefficient" is defined as Wi (Ci/Li - CS/Ls) Li Si Ci - (Li/Ls) Cs Si The wage rent coefficient can then be used in place of the household row coefficients in the direct requirements matrix in generating "wage rent" multipliers in lieu of the income multipliers. The wage rent multipliers yield estimates of changes in labor incomes stimulated by the exogenous change in demand, rather than the Eppgl wages, salaries and profits paid by the industry as a result of expansion of output which the traditional "income multi- pliers" provide. The reader should be cautioned that the "wage rent coefficient" is merely an attempt to deal with one of the problems posed by traditional multiplier analysis - i.e., the zero valuing of labor opportunity costs. The estima- tion procedure outlined in the above formula is based upon only a gross approximation of the real opportunity costs involved. Very seldom will the approximation be accurate. The basis upon which the approximation is accepted is that the arbitrary assumptions involved in its derivation con- stitute an improvement over the assumptions of the tradi- tional multiplier approach. Like the original multiplier 5*. 136 presentation, the above derivation is simplistic, and the mathematical symbols used reveal no great truths in them- selves. EstimatingProfit Changes Business profits are one of the hardest kinds of income to measure. Any business enterprise should be able to state accurately the sums that it has paid out in the course of a year as wages, interest and rents; it should be able to state also what income it has paid out to its owners. But the profits of the enterprise itself are not definite sums fixed by past transactions. On the contrary, they are appraisals of net changes in the position and prospects of the business as a whole--appraisals that look forward to the un- certain future as well as back to the irrevocable past. Like all mixtures of past history and future anticipations, statements of profits are necessarily subject to variable margins of un- certainty. Wesley C. Mitchell31 The Profit Component of Value Added In the preceding section, the division of the house- hold or the value added row of the direct requirement matrix into a wage component and a profit component was discussed. The procedure by which the wage component might be divided into an opportunity cost component and a rent component was outlined. The use of the rent com- ponent in devising "wage rent multipliers" as an alternative to "income multipliers" was discussed. Much of the discussion regarding the wage component is applicable to the discussion of the profit component. At least in concept, one should treat capital in much the 137 the same way as labor. The rents or quasi-rents which accrue to its employment should be treated as benefits; its opportunity costs should not be. The principle is, on the surface, a fairly simple one. In practice, however, the concept of returns to capital is very difficult to deal with. According to orthodox economic theory, quasi-rents are short-run returns to capital, after deducting variable costs. Quasi-rents can be divided into payments to cover fixed costs, and profits. Under pure competition, both are short-run returns, since in the long run the fixed costs become variable, and competition will drive all profits down to the "normal" return on capital. Thus, secondary benefits from the employment of fixed capital are theoretically short-run in nature. In the absence of market distortions which allow idle capacity or excess profits, no secondary benefits from capital employment would be possible. One might say that secondary benefits to capital employment arise out of errors in planning. This is especially true in the case of excess capacity, since its existence indicates that either too many plants or plants of the wrong size were built. Once the investment is made, it is considered to be irreversible or "sunk," in the short run. Thus, the surplus of gross receipts above Variable costs has traditionally been considered to con- Stitute a net benefit from capacity utilization. 138 In those cases in which plant capacity was being fully utilized EEQ excess profits were occurring in the industry, secondary benefits could also accrue. In this case, the benefits would consist of the surplus of gross receipts over both variable and fixed costs, since new capital in- vestment would be required if production were to be ex- panded. Thus, the "quasi-rents" would consist of only the ”pure profit" component, after deducting the "normal returns" to capital. It is possible to estimate the profit per dollar of sales component in the input-output matrix in the same manner as the wage component. The National Income Issues (July issue) of the Survey of Current Business provide data on profits before and after taxes by major industry group. By dividing the profit data by the sales data, one can ob- tain an average profit per dollar of sales for the year in question. There are, of course, problems involved in using such data in this manner. Some of these are the same problems which plague the input-output model: The problems of aggregation. In addition, there are the problems posed by the accountant's concept of profits versus the economist's concept.4 Accounting profits are very difficult to translate into the economic theory equivalent because of l) the effects of inflation on book values of capital assets, 2) the difficulty of estimating "user cost," 3) the difficulty posed by accelerated depreciation for tax purposes, and 4) the treatment of 139 re-invested profits. All of the tricks available to the accountant coupled with the competing corporate desires to show a good profit rate to the stockholders while hold- ing down tax liabilities make the interpretation of profit statements a precarious exercise.S Nevertheless, if one wishes to deal with the returns to capital, he has little choice but to use the profit data supplied by accountants. The alternative is to undertake very expensive primary research (which would be at least as costly as an input- output study) in an attempt to derive the relevant costs and state them in the precise concept of the economist. Some very competent economists have attempted to deal with this problem in the past.6 The results have largely been frustration and an equally cloudy "translation" of profit estimates. The basic reasons for the difficulties ex- perienced had to do with such things as: 1) Dealing with yearly "profits" where large year-to-year fluctuations occurred and the relevant "cycle" was difficult to deter- mine, 2) separating wage payments from profits in small firms, 3) valuing the alternative costs of the fixed assets used where the "economic" costs (especially user costs) depended upon anticipating future technology and demand, 4) separating the opportunity cost of capital, uninsured risk, and pure profit. Closely tied to determining the level of "profit" is the problem of defining profit rates and the real Oppor- tunity cost of capital. Because the fixed cost-variable 140 cost distinction is not nearly so clear in practice as it is in theory, it is very difficult to determine what con- stitutes investment and what constitutes recurrent expense. The simultaneous mix of a building having a life of forty years, a machine having a life of ten years (ignoring the rate of use and resultant user cost problems), another having a life of five years, "variable inputs" taking time periods ranging from one day to two years to put "on order" and/or use, and inventory accumulations with ware- house stays ranging from days to years creates serious difficulty in operationalizing the fixed cost-variable cost distinction. Since each of these assets might have been acquired at different times under different financing arrangements and "market" rates of interest, it is dif- ficult to determine the Opportunity cost of the capital invested in them by evaluating the alternatives at pur- chase dates. Using the current market value of the plant as the opportunity cost creates problems also, since the market value includes such intangibles as company image and "goodwill" as well as market contacts and purchase lines for variable inputs. As a result of these factors, estimates of industry rates of return on invested capital have been subject to wide margins of error, which has created great difficulty for analysts attempting to esti- mate industry profit rates. Thus, while one can readily be critical of the data on "accounting profits" which are 141 available in secondary sources, one is hard-pressed to find an alternative which can be effectively demonstrated to be superior. If one is willing to accept the profit data found in secondary sources, he still must decide between profits before and profits after taxes. Some tax payments are merely transfers, while others constitute payments to cover the costs of productive public services which are consumed by industry (the highway program is a good example of these). Net profits from the social vieWpoint lie some- where between the before and after tax profits. One can not readily say which figure would provide the closer estimate of profits net of both transfers and real cost of public services. However, since neither of the profit figures have been adjusted for risk and "normal” returns on investment, it is apparent that the profits before tax estimate greatly overstates the real net profits. At the same time, the profits after taxes estimate is also too high, unless the transfer component of the tax payment were equal to or greater than the level of "normal" returns expected in the industry. The actual relationship is not currently known nor easy to determine. It is improbable that the after-tax profits ". . . are in the form of a rent which could be taxed away and still allow . . . them to supply their services."7 Thus, they do not constitute real benefits to the owners from expanding output. Never- theless, the after-tax profits per dollar of sales is used her 35 prc her 311 cf 142 herein in estimating the changes in profits which occur as a result of secondary expansions in output. Of the choices available, these data appear to be most in keeping with the previously stated principle of attempting to arrive at the closest logically defensible estimate in reducing the margin between gross and net changes in income via secondary effects. It is the belief of the author that after-tax profits over state'the rents realized by pro- ducers. Much additional study of specific enterprises is required in order to answer questions regarding "excess profits" and scale economies. The convention adopted herein can only be defended on the grounds that it provides a more reasonable estimate than does the gross application of input-output multipliers. Rounds of Expansion and Benefit Creditability In the immediately preceding sections, it was stated that the net wage coefficients and the profit coefficients could be used in lieu of the household direct requirements coefficients in generating input-output multipliers. Such multipliers provide valuable information in dealing with some problems. However, they are, for the most part, in- appropriate for use in evaluating the secondary benefits from water resource development. iv 143 Associated Investments Most of the income multipliers generated from input- output models include both the direct and indirect effects of final demand changes. That is, they include not only the first round of transactions but also the infinite series of rounds which is supposedly generated (see Chapter IV). Unless unused capacity sufficient to meet all of these outputs exists, additional capital expendi- tures will be necessary. To give all of the credit for all ensuing income changes to the initial investment does great violence to all of the associated investments which are required to produce the induced outputs. It, in effect, assumes that all associated investments are riskless and that the supply of capital required to undertake them is perfectly elastic. The erroneous nature of such a con- vention is illustrated by the following example: The Corps of Engineers is dredging a channel which will allow a steel mill to expand its output of steel ingots. The problem is to estimate the income which will be generated as a result of increased purchases of inputs by the steel mill. The analyst used the traditional approach of using a direct-indirect income multiplier which includes the direct and indirect transactions of, among other things, large volumes of limestone. All of the income changes would be included as benefits under the traditional ap- proach. However, in order to provide for the greatly 144 increased purchases of limestone additional investments in quarrying equipment will be required. The credit for these investments are included in the secondary benefits from the investment in dredging. To illustrate the point fur- ther, assume that a second Corps of Engineers navigation project is required later to provide access to the lime- stone quarries necessitated by the increased steel output. The project benefits claimed for the second navigation project will include a sub-set of those claimed for the first project. Thus, not only is the credit for the effects of ensuing investments claimed by the first project, some of the effects are also double-counted in the Federal navi- gation program account or other development programs. Inelasticities of Supply The input-output multipliers project the current composition of input purchases and assume that the demands imposed on the input suppliers can be met at current prices. That is, projections using the model assume that the supply of all factors is perfectly elastic at prevailing prices. Obviously, this is not the case, especially for relatively large changes in demand such as those caused by large-scale water projects. These supply inelasticities restrict the final level of the real multiplier effects. It is difficult to estimate the exact extent of these restric- tions, because the relevant supply elasticities are not known. 145 Some analysts have introduced restraints into the model to adjust for these "leakages.” Isard and Kuenne8 dealt with the problem by excluding important sectors from the structural matrix, thus reducing the level of the in- direct effects which were calculated when the matrix was inverted. A principal sector which is often excluded is the household sector, thus eliminating the ”household induced" component (which is the principal component of the Keynesian Multiplier, see Chapter IV). A second method of restraining the multiplier has been to truncate the multiplier calculation after an arbitrarily selected number of rounds. Adjusting the Multiplier For the most part, "multipliers" provide an estimate of the absolute upper limit to the income changes which mighp occur as a result of a given exogenous change. They assume away the problems of friction, inflexibility, and "improper" reactions to stimuli that are present in any economy. Since they are designed for predicting rather than assigning cause, their use in investment analysis tends to lead to assigning the credit for all changes to the initial "exogenous" change occasioned by the invest- ment. The problems of "credit” assignment, leakages, and ancillary Government actions millitate against using the fUIl value of the direct and indirect effects generated 146 by most multiplier approaches. With each ensuing round of transactions included in the multiplier, these problems become more intense, and the justification for truncating the analysis becomes stronger. Even in the first round of induced transactions there are likely to be capital costs and risk undertakings which should receive part of the credit. In the absence of knowledge regarding the levels of leakages, credit, etc., any adjustment of the indirect effects is necessarily arbitrary. It is the author's be- lief that in few cases should more than the first round of transactions be included in the computation. The arbi- trariness of this judgement is realized, as is the justi- fication for sometimes carrying the computation a few rounds further. However, in light of the previously- discussed problems, it would appear that one is very sel- dom (if ever) justified in computing the rounds through to the full "multiplier" value. According to Clark, Grant, and Kalso, "The stemming-from hypothesis, crediting pro- duction of raw products as a 'trigger' and causing the chain of subsequent processes, has limited validity which does not warrant carrying the computation through to the ultimate consumer in all cases" (p. 26). The convention used herein is to use only the first-round direct requirements in com- puting the wage and profit gains. 147 Regional Coefficients and Purchases One of the major drawbacks to using input-output analysis in water resources research has been the lack of regional input-output studies in other than large metro- politan areas. In most cases, regional input-output studies are undertaken largely to provide data from which regional multipliers might be derived. The ever-increasing desire for sources from which such multipliers might be derived has led increasingly to the application of multipliers and/or study data from other areas deemed to be "comparable" to the region being analyzed. Input-output data from other regions having a similar industrial composition have been widely used in deriving local income multipliers because of the belief that "comparable" industry composition in- dicates comparable "leakages" from the local cycle of re- spending effects. The importance of "leakages" to the level-and, indeed, to the concept-of the multiplier has been discussed in previous chapters. The preceding sections have attempted to show the inapplicability of the "pure" multiplier concept to the evaluation of secondary effects of water resource projects. Tracing the inter-regional trade effects beyond the first round becomes increasingly difficult; and the assignment of "cause" for gains reali- zed from extra-regional trade (especially in regions al- ready enjoying "full employment") becomes increasingly difficult to justify. Limiting the analysis to one round 148 of transactions largely eliminates the need to measure round-after-round of leakages from re-spending and, thus, greatly reduces the advantages of the regional input- output study over the national one in estimating the local impacts. In fact, the national input-output model can be substituted for the regional model, if the analyst is suc- cessful in dealing with two issues: 1) Rationalizing the differences between direct requirements coefficients in the two models, and 2) separating "local" purchases from ”national" purchases so as to determine the extent of the impact upon local unemployed factors in cases in which the local unemployment rate exceeds the national rate. Differing Requirements Actually, the issue of rationalizing differing re- quirements is not nearly so problematic when the rounds of transactions are limited, since each iteration would have compounded any original difference in the coeffi- cients, especially when "leakages" (intra- as well as inter-regional) are considered. Since the direct require- ments coefficients are based largely on technical rela- tionships between inputs and outputs, they do not vary a great deal from one plant to the other; and in long run equilibrium, they should be essentially the same. The greatest difference in direct requirements coefficients grow out of differing systems of aggregation, rather than differing production processes. The greatest difference 149 in indirect requirements coefficients grow out of differing specifications of "leakages" between the models. Localizing Purchases There are basically two reasons for wishing to know the proportion of purchases which are local: 1) For estimating the real income effects where the local unem- ployment rate differs from the national, and 2) for deter- mining the inter-regional distribution effect of the pro- ject. Regional input-output studies provide this informa- tion directly. Additional data are needed in separating out the regional effects when using a national study. The secondary outputs to meet the new demands "caused" by the project might be supplied under any of the following three circumstances: 1) From firms (inside of our outside of the region) having excess plant capacity, 2) from marginal outputs from all firms (nationwide) who are operating at or near capacity, and 3) from new plants built specifically to supply the new demands. Under the first and third circumstances, one would expect transport economies to play a large role in localizing the effects within the region. Under the third, the location of new plants would depend upon the plants' "orientation."9 However, as discussed previously, the "credit" for gains realized from wholly new investments should not be given to the water project; though new plant investments are of great importance in designing programs and strategies for 150 promoting the development of depressed regions. The Corps of Engineers is sponsoring research directed towards as- sessing the plant location effects of water projects.10 However, until the direct link is proven and the "credit” assignment problem is solved (i.e., the "marginal product" of the water project in the location function is deter- mined), the addition of plant location effects as benefits in project appraisal only serve to add greater uncertainty and guesswork to the analysis and to intensify the diffi- culty of separating the net national gains from the transfers. The approach used herein is to assume that any "new" outputs which result from the impact of the 11 will be distributed project on "national" industries nationally in the same proportions as are current outputs. This amounts to an assumption that the national industries affected by the "stemming-from" impacts are not heavily input-oriented and that those affected by the "induced- by" impacts are not "market-oriented." (However, this does not imply that they are market-oriented and input- oriented, respectively.) It is also assumed that the "credit" due the project from ensuing rounds of transactions is approximately equivalent to that unduly assigned to the project in the first round of transactions. As previously discussed, this is very difficult to prove or disprove and constitutes an arbitrary assumption. The situation in which project-induced requirements are met by marginally increasing the output of all plants 151 is more straight-forward though perhaps less realistic than the other cases. In this case, it is almost defini- tional to assume that the inter-regional effects are dis- tributed in the same way as are present outputs. While it is unlikely that any plant would order one unit of the same item from every supplier of that item, under some circumstances the aggregate effect might approach this situation. The shifting and realigning of purchases which might occur when a large change in demand occurred in one locality could sift through much of the affected industry. It is unlikely, however, that the effects would be in exactly the same inter-regional proportions as the current capacity in most industries, largely because of transport economies. Nevertheless, the possibility of such an occurrence lends added credence to the convention of allocating inter-regional effects on the basis of current proportions. In those cases in which regional excess capacity existed in an affected industry, one would be justified in assuming that all of the induced output which could be supplied locally would come from local firms. In most cases, the existence of excess capacity should be known by the local offices of the water resource agencies. In many cases, the projects will have grown out of local support generated by the existence of this excess capacity. Especially in the non-metropolitan localities, the area offices should possess the knowledge of the local economy Ana wt.» 1‘) (D 152 sufficiently well to ascertain the local existence of ex- cess capacity in the industries to be affected by the water project. In these cases, the analyst should not allocate the impacts according to current inter-area proportions, at least until the excess capacity of the local firms has been absorbed. This would be true even in those cases in which excess capacity existed in other regions, since one would expect regional firms having excess capacity to be able to under-bid outside firms on the basis of trans- port costs and established market contacts. Of the two reasons, stated at the beginning of this section, for wishing to know the regional impact, only one has any impact on the "net benefits" of the project. Only in those cases in which regional labor and/or plant capacity are under-utilized relative to the nation is the total output affected. Where the utilization rates do not differ greatly from the national rates, such in- formation is largely secondary or irrelevant. Where local capacity is already fully utilized, local increases in output will require increased capital, which should re- ceive a part of the credit. Thus, the convention of proportioning the regional share according to existing proportions probably does little violence to the concept of "net" local project effects, under conditions of local "full employment." Where local conditions are such that the outputs can be met without additional investments, the “St local benefit concept conforms closely to the national 153 concept, and the localization issue is more important. Thus, the analyst should use his knowledge concerning local resource flows to construct the "proper" 10calization pro- portions for the industries affected. (He should also utilize his knowledge regarding local employment Oppor- tunities in attempting to construct a locally-relevant set of opportunity cost figures for local labor in improv- ing the wage rent coefficients discussed previously.) There is presently no widely available, reliable source of secondary data which would allow the analyst to readily pinpoint the existence of excess capacity, though there has been much research directed towards defining and determin- ing the existence of excess capacity.12 Unfortunately, the concepts of "capacity" and "capital investment," (and "profits") are components of capital theory, ". . . the . . 13 most e1u51ve concept of economics." It is perhaps axiomatic that the more "elusive" the concept, the dearer are the sources of data for dealing with it. The cases of profits and capacity lend credence to such an axiom. National and Local Industries. Leontief, in his 14 divided the industries study of the impact of an arms cut, into "local" and "National" categories on the basis of the proportion of sales going to local markets. Those indus- tries, such as personal services and wholesale and retail trade, which service basically local markets were classi- fied as "Local." The industries, such as primary metals 154 and other manufactured goods, which went primarily to "National" markets were classified as "National" industries. While there are some difficulties posed by the cate- gorizing of "Local" and "National" industries, this dif- ferentiation is helpful in the attempt to separate out the impacts which are primarily local and those which are national in getting at the problem of estimating inter- regional trade flows posed by the absence of a regional input-output study. As discussed in previous paragraphs, the analyst's personal knowledge of the local trade flow structure can be used to supplement this differentiation where there are ”National" industries which are servicing primarily local demands (such as a manufacturing concern which produces inputs which are wholly-used by another ”National" firm in the local area). Those industries which are classified as Local seldom sell in National markets. For the most part, their impacts can generally be considered to be wholly local. The reverse is not always true of the National industries, however, as alluded to in the preceding paragraph. While the National industries are not normally restrained by the location economies which effect the local industries, there are many examples of nationally-oriented firms whose out- puts go largely to the local area. In addition to input suppliers, there are also nationally-oriented firms sell- ing to "final demand" which sell largely within the local area. However, because of the scale economies involved 155 in the production and marketing of the products produced by such firms, the case of such National firms selling to local markets is most common in local areas which include large metropolitan areas. Localization Ratio. The approach used in the model is to use "Localization Ratios" to estimate the proportion of the national impacts which will occur locally. In the case of the "Local" Industries (as defined by Leontief), the Localization Ratio is assumed to be unity (1.0). That is, all of the sales which result from the secondary impacts on those industries are expected to occur locally. For those industries which are classified as "National," the Localization Ratio is based upon the proportion of total national employment in the industry located in the region. For example, if one-fourth of all employment in auto manu- facturing in the United States were located in the state of Michigan, the Localization Ratio for that industry for the state (defined as the ”region") would be 0.25. Thus, the model would assume that 25 per cent of all increases in auto sales would be supplied by production from the state of Michigan. Employment proportions obviously are not identical to capacity proportions, though they are very closelyre- lated. The convention of using employment as a basis for estimating localization is based upon two considerations: 1) The general availability of data-relating to employment 156 at sub-national levels in light of the lack of similar sources relating to other parameters of output capacity for sub-national areas, and 2) the fact that the major objec- tive of the model is to estimate wage changes -- thus, the employment sensitivity of the local industry is more impor- tant than its output capacity. Some might find the Localization Ratio an overly- simplistic tool for estimating the local proportion of the total impacts.' It admittedly extrapolates the average localization of employment to the marginal case, and eco- nomists are constantly cautioning against such procedures. It is not alone in this regard, however, since many applied economics techniques (including input-output models - see Chapter IV) have the same faults. In most cases, such extrapolations of average relationships are used because information regarding marginal relationships is impossible (or expensive -- i.e., uneconomic) to get. Thus, while economic theory generally deals with relationship at the margin, economic practice often deals in the application of data regarding averages. The pervasineness of this practice among economists does not justify the use of averages in marginal analysis; however, it does indicate the difficulty economists have experienced in developing data sources amenable to marginal analysis. 157 Applying the Model The preceding sections of this Chapter have dealt with the conceptual basis of the proposed model for estimating secondary benefits. Following sections of this chapter deal with the application of the model to the Detroit River, Trenton Channel Project, of the Army Corps of Engineers. The application serves two functions: First, it serves to demonstrate the procedures by which the model can be applied, and second, it generates an additional set of numbers to be used in Chapter VI in the comparison of alternative estimates of the secondary benefits of the Trenton Channel Project. The Trenton Channel Prpject The proposed Trenton Channel Project of the Army Corps of Engineers is a navigation project designed to provide access to deepwater transport for an extended portion of the Detroit River navigation channel. While there will be some side effects on recreation and the en- vironment, the basic economic impacts come from the pro- vision of lower cost transport.15 The principal user and primary beneficiary of the extended channel will be the McLouth Steel Company, which has indicated that it will expand its steel production, if the channel is extended. Ostensibly, an additional 3000 workers would be employed by the firm, and output of steel in the Detroit area would 158 expand by $40.5 million per year. The principal secondary impacts of the project would come via the increased pur- chases of inputs by the steel plant (induced-by), the in- creased purchases of inputs by users of the steel (stemming- from), and the purchases of inputs for the construction of the navigation channel. The Detroit metropolitan area - the principal "region" to be affected by the project is not an area of "chronic" unemployment. Rather, the employment problems of the area are cyclical because of the heavy dependence of the economy 16 Thus, the local re- upon durable goods manufacturing. sources which would be stimulated to employment by the navigation project should not be viewed as long-term un- employed resources, and the opportunity costs of those resources should be deducted from the secondary income generated, as discussed in preceding sections. The Computation Procedure Induced-byrBenefits Induced-by benefits are those which result from the increased purchases of inputs by local industries as a result of the provision of some water service - in this case navigation. The estimated increase in direct purchases of inputs by the McLouth Steel Company is shown in column 3 of Appendix Table l. The estimate is derived by multiply- ing the $40.5 million of increased steel sales by the 159 Direct Requirements Coefficients in column 2. The Direct Requirements Coefficients show the proportion of each dollar of sales of Primary Metals going for the purchase of inputs from each sector. For example, for every dollar of sales of Primary Metals, $0-02994 goes for the purchase of Electricity, Gas and Water Services. Thus, $40.5 million in steel sales results in $1,213,000 in purchases of Electricity, Gas and Water. The other entries in column 3 are similarly derived (i.e., $40.5 million x .00007 = $3,000;$40.5 million x .04657 = $1,886,000; etc.). The secondary sales shown in column 3 indicate the first round of "activity" generated by the increase in steel sales (see Chapter IV). This does not represent net benefits to anyone, since these are merely payments for productive services which also have costs associated with their production. The proportion of induced sales which go for the purchase of labor by each affected industry can be esti- mated by multiplying the "Labor Coefficients" in column 4 by the respective induced sales in column 3. The Labor Coefficients show the proportion of each sales dollar (for the industries arrayed on the left of the table) which goes to purchase labor inputs (i.e., 42.24% of gross receipts by Electricity, Gas and Water producers are paid out in wages and salaries. Thus, $1,213,000 in sales results in $561,000 in payments to labor). The total wages and salaries generated can be obtained by summing column 5. 160 Again, column 5 does not represent the first round induced benefits to labor, unless all of the laborers employed had absolutely no other productive alternative use. As dis- cussed previously, this is the estimate used for the labor component in traditional income multiplier approaches. The number of workers effected can be estimated by dividing the induced wages in each industry by the average production worker wage in that industry shown in column 6. Thus, for Electricity, Gas and Water, an addition of 74 workers (column 7) will be required as a result of the increased demand posed by the expansion of the steel plant. These represent "new" jobs only if they will be supplied by previously unemployed resources. Under "full employment" conditions, they must be filled by workers from another industry. In the model, it is assumed that they will be filled by workers previously employed in the Service in- dustry. Thus, the "net" wages received by each new worker in the Electricity, Gas and Water industry will not be $7,500 as shown in column 6, but, rather, it will be $7,500 minus the $4,765 which was being earned in the Service industry; the difference ($2,735) is shown in column 8. Similarly, the difference between $4,765 and $6,180 (i.e., $1,415) would represent the increase in wages for those who shift from Services to the Printing and Publishing industry. By multiplying the "Wage Rents" in column 8 by the "Workers Affected" shown in column 7, one can estimate the total change in wages resulting from the 161 induced effects of the expansion in steel production. This total for each industry is shown in column 9. The reader might note that the entry for the Service industry in column 9 is zero. The analysis says that there are no induced effects upon the Services industry. However, column 7 shows an increase of 58 in the demand for Service workers. While the model assumes that 1,021 workers are being drawn away from the Service industry and into new jobs. This should result in a deficit of 1,079 Service workers relative to the demand for outputs from the Services sector. The degree to which this represents an induced disbenefit depends upon the elasticity of supply and demand for services as compared to that for the other outputs produced by the workers attracted away from the Services industry. Under conditions other than total unemployment, there will be some cost associated with stimulating factors to "higher" employment. The convention of subtracting the earnings in the Service sector from those in the "higher" employment makes certain assumptions about the utility realized from the production and consumption of services. The simplest means of dealing with the welfare changes posed is to assume that the market for services is com- petitive, such that the marginal utility from services consumption is equal to its price. Assuming that the total utility was captured by service workers in the form of pay- ments for services, the wage rent estimated in the model 162 would represent the real welfare gains involved in the shift of the marginal worker. The validity of extending this "marginal" relationship to all 1,079 workers affected de- pends upon the slope of the aggregate marginal utility function for services consumption relative to the marginal productivity of the 1,079 service workers. The greater the slope of the function in this range relative to the marginal product of service labor, the greater will be the discrepancy between real negative changes in welfare and the opportunity cost accounting embodied in the price of service labor. The model assumes that both are hori- zontal and equal and that the wages paid to service workers represents the total utility realized in the production and consumption of services. The net wage gains shown in column 9, then, represent "real" changes in welfare, under these assumptions. The net wage gains shown in column 9 are the esti- mated gains for the nation as a whole. To estimate the proportion which accrues to the Detroit area, the "Locali- zation Ratios" in column 10 are multiplied by the respective figures in column 9. (The derivation of the Localization Ratios is discussed in the preceding section of this 17 The Localization Ratio for the Local Indus- chapter). tries is set a 1.0, as discussed above. Thus, that portion of column 11 is identical to column 9. However, the local proportion of the induced-by effects upon the National Industries is a much smaller proportion of the 163 total effects -- an average of 2.84 per cent in this case. As a result, the total "local" effects in terms of wage changes is estimated to be about 37 per cent of the total "national" wage effects. Whether this proportion would be estimated from a regional input-output model of the Detroit area can be determined only when such a model be- comes available. The wage gains estimated in Appendix Table l were estimated without the use of the wage rent coefficient dis- cussed above. This was done in order to show the process through which the wage rent coefficient operates. Using the wage rent coefficient, columns 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 could be replaced by one column (or one "vector," if matrix procedures are used. See Schmid and Ward, 0p cit, Ap- pendix). The wage rent coefficient (for Electricity, Gas and Water, for example) can be computed by dividing column 8 by column 6 and multiplying the quotient by column 4 (e.g., 2735/7500 x .4624 = .1686). Multiplying column 3 by this wage rent coefficient yields column 9. The wage rent coefficient is used throughout the remainder of this study rather than the longer procedure used in Appendix Table 1. The computation of profit gains is similar to that of wage gains, except that the "Profit Rents" are obtained directly by assuming them to be approximated by "profits after taxes." The induced sales in column 1 of Appendix Table 2 are multiplied by the average after-tax profits 164 per dollar of sales coefficients of column 2. The result is column 4 showing the profit gains induced by the steel expansion. The Detroit portion is then estimated by applying the Localization Ratios of column 4 to the Profit Gains. Thus, it is estimated that $208,530 in Profit Gains accrue in the Detroit area of the $951,061 which accrue to the nation as a whole. The sum of the Wage Gains and Profit Gains induced by the steel Output for the Detroit Region is estimated at $1,204,728, while that for the nation as a whole is estimated to be $3,680,783. Stemminngrom Benefits. Stemming-from benefits are those increases in wages and profits which result from increased availability of inputs into other production processes. The readiest example is that of the increased supply of agricultural products to food processors as a result of an irrigation project. Stemming-from benefits have not been as widely treated in the literature as have induced-by benefits. This is because (as discussed in Chapter II) stemming-from 18 while traditional benefits are basically supply effects, multiplier analysis has dealt with demand effects. At the national level when wide-scale unemployment does not exist, a water resource project should produce stemming-from (supply) effects to help the economy to absorb the induced-by (demand) effects without simply 165 creating inflation. Ideally, the supply and demand effects would be commensurate, so that the "multiplier" indicated real income changes. As argued by Clark, pp_gl, one should not add together supply and demand in estimating national secondary benefits, since the two act jointly in deter- mining equilibrium output. However, at the regional level, the two effects can be additive, since the increased out- puts outside Of the region might have grown out of the inter-regional "leakages" of the induced-by (demand) ef- fects of the project. However, these "leakages" are not included as regional induced-by imports. Thus, the stemming-from (supply) effects allow some of the inter- regional effects of the project to be recaptured by the project region. As a result, stemming-from benefits are only regional in nature and should not be included as "net" benefits from the national standpoint (i.e., though they are "real" benefits to the project region, from the national standpoint they are simply transfers which cancel out somewhere else). Even from the viewpoint of the region, the stemming-from effects are net for only those increased output which are exported from the region, since those sold internally largely go to satisfy the increased intra- regional demand created by the "induced-by" effects. Stemming-from effects constitute special problems for the analyst, since their validity depends upon the im- portance of the water project-related factor in further 166 production processes. Of great importance are the elastici- ties of substitution of the relevant factors and their elasticities of supply with and without the water project. As discussed in Chapter II, a serious drawback to most analyses of stemming-from impacts has been the tendency to assume the perfect elasticity of all factors, besides the water project-related factor. It was pointed out in Chapter II that such an assumption creates an inverse relationship between the stemming output and the propor- tion of production costs represented by the water project- related factor. The problems of "importance" of factors are dealt with in the model by adopting a convention assuming that the proportion of the sales dollar going to each factor indi- cates its relative importance in the production process. Thus, a factor whose cost represents 20 per cent of the sales dollar of some product is twice as "important" in the production process as a factor which absorbs 10 per cent. These percentage weights are used as a rough means of adjusting the stemming outputs to account for inelas- ticities of other factors and for the tendency to assign credit in an inverse fashion. The approach used in the model does have some basis in economic theory, since normally the "credit" assigned to each input should be re- lated to its value in producing the final output. If the input prices reflect their marginal value products (as they should under perfectly functioning input markets), then 167 the average outlay for water project-related inputs per dollar of sales is a good approximation of the credit which should be given to the water project for the stemming-from output. In Appendix Table 3, the outputs of steel are dis- tributed among the steel using industries in the propor- tions indicated by the 1963 National Input-Output Study. The distribution coefficients, are arrayed in column 1. Column 1 indicates that Primary Metals production receives the greatest share of primary steel output - i.e., approxi- mately 20 per cent. Multiplying these coefficients by the $40.5 million increase in steel output yields column 2 showing the expected distribution by industrial purchaser of the project-related steel output. Primary Metals, for example, will purchase $8,279,820 of the output (i.e., $50.5 million x .204). The value of purchases of steel by each sector is taken to represent the portion of stem- ming effects which can be credited to the increased availa- bility of steel, as a result of the weighting scheme dis- cussed in the preceding paragraph. Since primary steel inputs absorb 20.4 per cent of each dollar of sales of the primary metals industry, the stemming output under the traditional assumption regarding the elasticity of other factors would be estimated at $39,730,000 (i.e., $8,279,820/ .20840). The convention of crediting the stemming outputs in proportion to the input costs results in multiplying the total output of $39,730,000 by the relative weight of 168 .20840, which gives the original steel sales figure of $8,279,820. The same is true for each sector affected. Thus, the sales of steel to each industry shown in column 2 represent also the portion of stemming output creditable to the increased steel production. The Profits and Wage Rents are computed in the same manner for the stemming-from benefits as for the induced-by benefits, with one exception. Since only the exports of the increased outputs create net gains to the region, the local sales of steel must be isolated and ex- cluded from the computations. Locally-contained demand effects must be spent upon locally-produced goods in order to generate the wage and profits estimated in the induced- by effects. Thus, the local stemming-from effects are simply the counter part of the induced-by effects. Stemming-from production is available for export, only if the local stemming-from effects exceed the local induced-by effects for a particular sector. For example, the induced-by effects upon the Printing and Publishing sector (Appendix Table 1) increases the demand for Printing and Publishing by $3,000. (All of these demands are as- sumed to be local). For this demand increase to affect wages and profits in that sector, an output response must be made by the sector. Unless the supply of Printing and Publishing is perfectly elastic, the project-related demand increase can not be given full credit for the response, in the absence of a commensurate project-related 169 supply effect. Column 2 of Appendix Table 3 indicates that the stemming-from (supply) effect on Printing and Publishing is $3,240. Thus, $240 in "eXportable surplus" Printing and Publishing services are created. Only the Profit Rents and Wage Rents which accrue to this $240 in Printing and Pub- lishing "exports" is included as local stemming-from bene- fits. The derivation is straight-forward for the "Local Industries," since the Localization Ratio is 1.0. For the National Industries, the surplus (deficit) from the na- tional vieWpoint must be determined first. Then any sur- plus production is apportioned according to the Localiza- tion Ratios. For example, the National "surplus" of non- durable goods amounts to $453,190 (i.e., $809,190 minus $376,000). Since 0.12 per cent of that industries employ- ment (capacity) is located in Detroit, $544 of the expor- table surplus is estimated to accrue to the Detroit Region. The Wage and Profit Rents on this $544 of "exports" are included as Detroit Region stemming-from benefits. The same procedure is followed in calculating the stemming- from benefits for the other industrial sectors. Those for which the induced-by effects exceed the stemming-from effects are assumed to produce no "surplus." Thus, there is no stemming-from benefit computed for them. The total of Wage and Profit Rents due to stemming-from effects is $368,383. Construction Impacts: Induced-By. In addition to the secondary impacts from project-related output expansions 170 there are also secondary impacts which occur as a result of project construction expenditures. The construction effects are basically induced-by effects or aggregate demand effects. The generation of secondary income via construction expenditures represents the point at which water resource develOpment policy comes most directly into line with the policy of aggregate demand maintenance voiced in the Employment Act of 1946. While the induced-by and stemming-from effects from project outputs are to some extent mutually self-effectuating, the induced-by effects from construction expenditures depend wholly upon existent flexibility (i.e., supply elasticity) in the economy to make their multiplier effects "real." In the absence of such flexibility, the "balanced budget multiplier" effects of the tax-expenditure sequence is lost on inflation, and little or no real income changes result. The induced-by effects are largely inter-regional changes in incidence of income, since (from the project-by-project vieWpoint of local interests - see Schmid and Ward, p. 38-41) the project region receives a large part of the construction impact while paying a small part of the cost. Part of the inter-regional income re-distribution could represent real gains, if the project region were experiencing under- employment conditions while the rest of the nation was not. However, such conditions did not prevail in the Detroit area during the period relevant to the analysis presented herein. Thus, in this analysis the construction impacts 171 are treated as inter-regional income transfers, and in- clusion is made only in the regional account. The estimation of the secondary impacts induced-by the construction of the Trenton Channel Project follows essentially the same lines as the procedure used in esti- mating the changes induced by the steel output, with two exceptions: l) The vector of direct requirements is 19 rather than taken from the Haveman and Krutilla study the 1963 Input-Output Study, and 2) only the local portion of the induced-by impacts are counted. The direct require- ments vector in this case shows the distribution of each dollar of Federal expenditure for dredging. For example, 10.3 percent of the costs spent in the Non-durable goods industry. Multiplying this vector by the construction cost of the project ($31,400,000) gives the estimated impact by industrial sector. Following the procedures outlined previously, the Detroit Region impact from the construction expenditures is estimated in Appendix Tables 5 and 6 to be $309,310 in Wage Gains and $174,611 in Profit Gains, respectively. TrentopyPrpject Secondary Benefits Summarized The secondary benefits of the Trenton Channel Navi- gation Project have been estimated in the above sections from two viewPoints: 1) That of the Detroit Region and 2) that of the nation as a whole. The estimation procedure attempted to find means of estimating the real net changes 172 in income which accrued at both levels as a result of the project. The defects of simplifying the various reactions and interactions into such a two part framework have been 0 widely discussed.2 Nevertheless, since this convention was the format suggested in the Water Resource Council Task Force Report, an attempt was made herein to work within such a framework. The secondary benefits from the Detroithegion view- point consist of $996,198 in Wage Gains induced-by the steel mill expansion, $208,530 in profit gains stemming-from the steel mill expansion, $309,310 in Wage Gains induced-by project construction expenditures, and $174,611 in Profit Gains induced-by project construction expenditures. The sum of these effects is $2,055,584. From the National viewpoint, the secondary benefits consist of only the Wage and Profit Gains induced-by the increased steel output. The estimated National Wage Gains total $2,729,672, while the Profit Gains total $951,061. The sum of the two is $3,680,733. However, since there were no unemployed resources in the Detroit area, there were probably no National indirect benefits at all, after accounting for declines in other sectors. The Underlying_Assumptions of the Model Within the scope of the limits defined, The results have been quite conclusive: That assuming the assumptions That have been assumed 21 The problem becomes unobtrusive. 173 The distinguished planner and development economist, Albert Waterston, has noted that economic planners often provide plans of little practical value because of the re- strictive assumptions which are made. He points out that Because analytical complexity increases with the number of variables used, planners include as few variables as possible in their closed system models and rely on ceteris paribus or mutatis mutandis to maintain control over the ex— cluded variabIes. This approach necessarily con- stricts the limits of possible answers. By posing questions which are shielded from outside distur- bance or uncertainty, answers are bound to be simplistic; by narrowing the scope of problems, solutions are sure to be circumscribed.2 The essence of model building is simplification. The objective is the optimization of the competing desires for conceptual manageability and prescriptive relevance to a complex world. This "two-horned dilemma" pervades prac- tically all of economic analysis, and, unfortunately, its dangers are not always recognized and appreciated by economic practitioners. The proliferation of econometric and mathematical models which purported to "simplify reality" and/or make economic analysis more "scientific" during the 1960's bears ample witness to the ever present danger of "losing sight of reality in a maze or pretentions and unhelpful symbols." The assumptions which surround any analysis often constitute the key to understanding the problem which is being analyzed. As pointed out above, simplifying assump- tions are a necessary part of model building, if the objective of the model is to make understandable the 174 fundamental relationships involved. Yet, the assumptions themselves constitute real variables (exogenously defined) whose relationship to the endogenous variables must also be understood, if the analyst is to draw the full measure of the heuristic value of his analysis. Sometimes, (as was suggested in the quotation introducing this section) it turns out that the assumptions a priori specify the most important variables in the analysis, and the results be- come foregone conclusions, thus destroying much of the value of the "analysis." The objective of this section is to attempt to deal with the problems posed by the assumptions made in the analysis in preceding sections. The explicit assumptions of the model, most of which were discussed in the text, will be outlined. An attempt will be made to identify the implicit assumptions and to spell them out. The underlying assumptions (as best they can be delineated by the author) will be presented so that the reader might make his own analysis of their effects. The result, it is hoped, should aid both the author and the reader in interpreting the validity of the model and of its results. Assumptions Common to Multiplier Analysis 1. There are no negative local indirect impacts from the acquisition of funds to build the project by the public sector. The situations in which this would be true are: 175 a) "Money creation" equal to the public expendi- ture, b) Bond sales which were paid for from "hoarded" savings, c) A balanced budget multiplier equal to the estimated indirect effect of the project, or d) All money used for project cost comes from taxes in pphg: regions 2. The money invested in the project would not other- wisse: have been spent. Otherwise, the multiplier impact WOLl].d have occurred anyway. 3. Federal monetary and fiscal policy will continue to t>e administered such that the employment rates and re- sultant opportunity costs will not change during the time Period under analysis. 4. The total supply effects of the stemming-from i”fl?a&:ts and existent supply elasticities are sufficient to <2cnnp1ement the induced-by effects at current price levels. Otherwise, the demand multiplier effects would Create mostly inflation. 5. Changes in personal income represent "equivalent" ChaJlges in inter-personally comparable social welfare. Otherwise, the comparison of income changes is not a good we 1 f are measure . 176 Assumptions Common to Input-Output Models 1. All of the production functions involved are liliearly homogeneous: The marginal factor-factor and fac:tor-product relationships do not change as output ex- paJldS. 2. The composition of input purchases and the dis- tiriloution of outputs remain the same as output increases in each indus try . .Additional Assumptions From Conventions in Rent Model 1. All purchases of inputs from firms classified as "Local" come from within the project region. This as- sumption was implemented through the assignment of locali- zation ratios equal to unity (1.0) for the "Local" indus- tries. 2. Purchases of inputs from industries classified as "PJational" are distributed inter-regionally in the same proPortion as is employment in those industries. This assumption was reflected in the localization ratios, which were derived by dividing employment in the particular in- duEYtry in the project region by the employment in that in- dufiStiy'in the nation as a whole. This assumption and the immediately preceding assumption were made in attempting t" determine the lpppl impacts using a mppipmpl input- O'uliput model. 177 3. The "National" industries which are effected by the: project are not input-market-oriented. This assumption resnilts from the restraints imposed by the localization rat:ios also. If the National industries were input-market— oriJented, the localization ratios would greatly understate the: proportion of induced-by sales which would come from the project region. 4. The "Local" industries which are effected by thi? project are output-market-oriented. All of the sales of' Isocal industries are assumed to go to the project regipn. 5. The marginal wages paid equal the average wages fcxr each effected industry. Thus, each new job created ill teach industry adds one new worker at the "average" wage foz‘ that industry. 6. The average alternative cost is equal to the average production worker wage in the lowest paying in- ‘hlstkry in the region. This assumption is related to the metihod of computing the Wage Rent Coefficient. Since the reall- alternatives for each worker was not known, it was assumed for computational purposes that the alternative would be at least equal to the average wage in the lowest wage sector. 7. The surplus of actual profits over the profits which would be required to bring about the current rate of ‘PTOduction is equal to after-tax profits. This amounted t0 the assumption that all "take-home" profits were a 178 surplus which could be taxed away without affecting out- put. 8. The marginal rate of profit rent is equal to the average rate for each industry affected. The "average profit rent" was assumed to be equal to the after-tax profit rate. This rate was used in computing the rates for any change in induced sales. 9. Declines in employment occur only in jobs whose overall average wages are equal to those in the lowest wage industry; declines in production occur only in those industries which are earning no profits. This assumption is implicit in the Rent Model, since the model traces only the expansions and not the contractions which occur in the system. The subtraction of the "alternative" wages from the new wages attempts to adjust for these changes on the employment side. Declines in production are partly dealt with by the assumption made elsewhere that the demand change is "new" demand and not a shift. Failure to account for profit contractions due to labor resource price in- creases are "justified" by assuming zero profitability of contracting industries. 10. The total rents which are generated in the first round of expansion are equal to the portion which is creditable to the project from all rounds of expansion. The problem of assigning credit for all rounds of expansion was "assumed away" by adopting the convention of assigning 179 only the credit for the rents generated in the first round to the project. 11. The relative cost of each factor in each in- dustry indicates its relative marginal value product in that industry. Since the production functions are linearly homogeneous, the marginal value products do not change as output increases (and inputs are added in constant pro- portions). This assumption arose from the convention of assigning stemming-from credit on the basis of the pro- portion of total cost in the stemming-from production process which was represented by the project output. 12. Net marginal social utility in the consumption of goods produced by the industries which decline is equal to zero (for all units by which production is cur- tailed). The welfare of producers in the declining in- dustries was dealt with in assumption 9, above. However, the welfare of consumers of those products must also be dealt with. The simplest procedure is to assume that all consumers of the products no longer available were 223 realizing any "consumers surplus" from the consumption of those commodities. That is, the demand for those commodi- ties was perfectly elastic. 180 Footnotes l. A. Allan Schmid and William Ward, A Test of Federal Water Project Evaluation Procedures With Emphasis onCRegional Income and Environmentaliguality (East Lansing: April 1970). 2. The closest relationship is found between the proportion of large firms in a particular industry and the average wage rate for the industry. Generally, the greater the proportion of large firms, the higher are the average wages. See Stanley H. Masters, "An Interindustry Analysis of Wages and Plant Size," The Review of Economics and Statistics (August 1969). 3. "The Problem of Measuring Profits: A Preliminary Note by Wesley C. Mitchell" in Ralph C. Epstein, Indus- trial Profits in the United States, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (New York: 1934), 4. 4. George J. Stigler, Capital and Rates of Return in Manufacturing Industries (Princeton: 1963). 5. U. S. Congress, Profits: Report of a Sub- Committee of the Joint Committee on the Economic Report on Profits'Hearinge (Washington: 1949). 6. For example Stigler, o cit, and Ralph C. Epstein, Industrial Profits in the United States (New York: 1934). 7. Huffschmidt, et a1., Standards and Criteria for Formulatin and Evaluatin Federal Water Resource Develep- ments (Was ington: June 0, 1961). 8. "The Impact of Steel Upon the Greater New York- Philadelphia Industrial Region." The Review of Economics and Statistics (November 1953). 9. That is, whether the firm were "product market oriented" or "factor market oriented." See Isard, et a1., Methods of Regional Analysis, Chapter 7. 10. See, for example, Calvin S. Schneider, Proce- dures Manual for DeterminingPreliminary Empansion Benefits fer AppalaCHianIWater Prejects, (Lexington: 1968). ‘ 11. "National" industries are those which sell primarily to national markets. 12. See Edwin Kuh, "Unemployment, Production Functions, and Effective Demand," Journal of Political Economy (June 1966). 181 13. Oskar Morgenstern, On the Accuracy of Economic Observations (Princeton: 1950). 14. Wassily Leontieff, et a1., "The Economic Impact- Industrial and Regional of An Arms Cut," The Review of Economics and Statistics (August 1965). 15. Schmid and Ward, op cit. 16. Ibid. 17. The Localization Ratio for Stone, Clay and Glass products was set at zero, because the principal input purchased from that sector by the steel industry is lime- stone, which comes from outside of the region. See Schmid and Ward, op cit, 29-30. 18. Clark, et a1., op cit. 19. Unemployment, Idle Capacity, and the Evaluation of Public Expenditures: tNatiOnal and Regional Analysis (Baltimore: 1968), 20-21. 20. See A Summary Analysis of Nineteen Tests of Proposed Evaluation Procedures on’Selected Water and Land Resource Projects, Report totthe Water Resource CounciI by the Special Task Force (Washington: July 1970). 21. William A. Ward, "Economic Research: Prologue and Epilogue," American Journal of Agmicultural Economics (February 1970). 22. ”Resolving the Three-Horned Planning Dilemma," paper presented at a meeting of the American Society of Planning Officials, New Orleans, March 29, 1971. CHAPTER VI A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF TWELVE SECONDARY BENEFIT APPRAISALS Overview In Chapter II, the different concepts and definitions of secondary benefits were discussed. Three general cate- gories of such benefits were delineated. In Chapter IV, the different methods of estimating one of these cate- gories, the multiplier impacts, were discussed. In Chap- ter III, the concept of "rent multipliers" was introduced and discussed as an alternative to the traditional "income multipliers," and in Chapter V a model designed to estimate the rents creditable to the initial project was discussed and used in estimating the secondary rents from the Trenton Channel Project. In the closing section Of Chapter V, the underlying assumptions of the model were delineated, and the role of assumptions in economic analysis were briefly discussed. In Chapter VI, the "customary" variety of secondary benefits from four Federal water resource projects are looked at. In the case of each project, three different estimates come from the reports submitted by the Test Teams which tested the Water Resource Council's proposed 182 183 evaluation procedures as presented in June 1969. The third estimate comes from the application of the model which was presented in Chapter V to the respective projects (see Appendix). The objective of this comparative analysis is to determine the differences in analysis and in results which might arise from differing concepts regarding second- ary benefits (the "customary" variety) and from differing methodological approaches to dealing with them on the part of different analysts. In the sections of this chapter which immediately follow, the concepts, beliefs and assumptions which are discernible from the reports to the Water Resource Council by the Test Teams are discussed. This discussion reveals significant differences among the Test Teams regarding the concept of secondary benefits. Several different measures are proposed by the teams, as well as several methods of estimating the relative magnitude of the measures suggested. Widely differing assumptions are discerned regarding the state of the economy and aggregate demand maintenance. Other assumptions regarding resource mobility and inter- regional employment differences are also seen. Tables 2, 3, 4, and 5 outline the assumptions and beliefs of each of the Test Teams regarding the evaluation of secondary bene- fits. In Table 6 the secondary benefit estimates of each of the Test Teams are presented, along with those generated by the model presented in Chapter V of this study. As can be 184 TABLE 1 After-Tax Profits Per Dollar of Sales Compared With Before- Tax Profit Rates Reduced by Fifty Per Cent Before-Tax Profits/$ After-Tax Sales/2a -Profits/$ Salesb Local Industries Electricity, Gas 8 Water .0891 .0873 Printing 8 Publishing .1016 .0512 Transportation 8 Warehousing .0272 .0135 Wholesale 8 Retail Trade .0121 .0146 Communications .1016 .0943 Services .0235 .0219 Construction --- .0160 National Industries Metal Ores Mining .0604 .0403 Coal Mining .0263 .0355 Non-durable Goods .0338 .0371 Lumber 8 Wood Products .0283 .0402 Chemicals 6 Allied Products .0338 .0615 Primary Metals .0450 .0547 Fabricated Metals .0339 .0438 Stone, Clay 6 Glass Products .0416 .0464 Non-electrical Machinery .0522 .0533 Electrical Machinery .0399 .0415 Motor Vehicles .0527 .0557 Other Transportation Equip .0296 .0319 Instruments .0747 .0782 Misc-Manufacturing .0309 .0386 aAs used in Schmid and Ward, op cit, p. 35. bSee Appendix Table 2, Column 2. Trenton Channel Project: 185 TABLE 2 Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation Corps of Engineers Test Team Michigan State University Test Team Definition of Secondary Benefits Changes in employment and income stimulated by the project. Increased stability. 'Changes in rents to factors stimu- lated to higher employment by the project. Measure of Benefits Used (Suggested) National vs. EmpIOyment generated in steel and related sector and induced employment in "service" sector. Alltreal benefits in DiffErence in wages generated by sector and lowest alternative wages available to those workers. "Abnormal" profits earned on increased output. Some regional ih- Regional regional account belong come gains are Benefits in National. Regional transfers from benefits at expense of other regions. other regions should not National gains are be counted as benefits. arrived at only after netting out the transfers. Estimation EmpIOyment Base Multi- Input-output, Procedure Used plier sectoral multipli- (Suggested) ers, adjusted for alternative wages. EXplicit 1. Extensive growthiin 1. All employment and Detroit represented in- generated would be Implicit tensive National grthh supplied by labor- Assumptions 2. LaBorers employed by ers from Service and Beliefs plant were earning lower sector ("under- V of Test wage in other region employment"benefits) Teams 3. Extensive growth in 2. Expansion of Detroit is good from the local viewpoint 4. Basic/non-basic ratio is stable outputs and inputs will be linear 3. No supply in elasticities in first round 4. Half of profits are "abnormal" 5. Localization of impacts would be equal to current empleyment ratios 186 TABLE 2 (Continued) Corps of Engineers Michigan State Test Team University Test Team Formula and/or Et = 3 0 31) (31h - ash) value of E - E ° , _ . multiplier t nb Where. aij - direct Where: Et = total requirement from in- Rounds of Expansion employment in the region Enb = regional employment in non-basic (i.e., service) industries Infinite dustry i per dollar of sales by industry j, aih = value added per dollar of sales by industry i aSh = value added per dollar of sales by service industry One round Stonewall Jackson Reservoir: 187 TABLE 3 Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation Definition of Secondary Benefits Relevant Benefit Parameter National vs. Regional Benefits EStimation Procedure Used Corps of Engineers Test Team Wages, salaries 6 profits from invest- ments wholly or partly induced to locate in region by project Employment andw personal income Regional =‘National if resources used would have been un- employed; otherwise no national bene- fits Economic Base Multiplier Cornell University Test Team ” Regional: Change in real regional income. National: Payment to previously unemployed factors when water project is clearly a constraint to growth Per capita thange in real income - i.e., intensive income rowth oth can occur. Re- gional might be trans- fers from other regions, however, (Input-output model, induced multiplier) ESuggested) xp 1cit and Implicit Assumptions and Beliefs of Test Teams Formula and70r Value of Multiplier ll Basic-non basic regional income grows. 2. Alter- native factor earn- ings equal zero 3. Perfect factor markets in other regions; imperfect factor markets in project region ET and YT Ht ‘ ENB YT ‘ YN13 Where: ET = total regional employment ENB = non-basic (service employment in the region, YT = total regional income YNB = non-ba51c (service) income in the region ll. Migrants earn no ratio is constant as rent. 2. Only un- employed factors can create real national gains. 3. Labor supply and aggregate supply not perfectly elastic. 4. "Use ex- ternalities" exist but cannot be evalu- ated 2.36 adjusted to‘l.8 to reflect supply inelasticities 188 TABLE 3 (Continued) Corps of Engineers Cornell University Test Team Test Team Rounds of Infinite Truncated at 1/2 total Expansion effects to adjust for supply inelasticities Poteau Watershed Project: 189 TABLE 4 Corps of Engineers Test Team Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation Soil Conservation Service Test Team Definition of ——r Growth in income per Net income effects of Secondary capita (intensive), Second and following Benefits after deducting in- round of expansion. flation effects Relevant EXtensive employment Multiplier effects of Benefit growth. (Change in difference between Parameter real income) poultry processing National vs. Regional Benefits E§timation Procedure Used (Suggested) Explicit and Implicit Assumptions and Beliefs of Test Teams Equal, if unemplOyed resources existed in project area Employment BaselMult. (Keynesian Multiplier) (Input-output multi- plier (Comparative projec- tion) 1. All resources used would be unemployed otherwise. 2. gate supply not per- fectly elastic (in- flation). 3. All multipliers yield same results. 4. Marginal utility of Regional income = national average Aggre- wages and unemploy- ment compensation. National multiplier = 3.85. Regional = 1.57 because of "leaka es." Multip ier transplant lTiResource alloca- tion frictions (not barriers) existed which would take 20 years to overcome. 2. Water shortage was effective "bottle- neck." Formula and/Or l - . . Value of (I-MPL suggested) giéigfizij 13§§§’ Multiplier ET = 1 65 d Local "induced by": W ° use 1.10 Where: MPC = Marginal Propensity to consume ET = total regional employment ENB = regional non- basic (service) employment Reunds Of* Infinite Infinite Expansion Mountain Home Project: 190 TABLE 5 Outline of Test Team Approaches to Secondary Benefit Estimation Corps of Engineers Test Team University of Wisconsin Test Team Definition of Secondary Benefits Increase in level and stability of personal income. More diverse economic base. More jobgepportunities Change in rents realized by factors affected, both posi- tive and negative Measure of Benefits Used (Suggested) First roufid Of multi- plier generated by Team actually used gross income from recreation expendi- tures Income from first round of agricul- tural sales and purchases. (Change in ESE income of factors). National vs. Regiona1==National. Partly competitive; Regional Unemployed resource partly complementary. benefits equal in two Net national gains accounts, though are "probably minimal." EstimatiOn Multiplier Transplant Input-output. Procedure Used for irrigation effects. Sectoral multipliers (Suggested) Base multiplier for Recreation develop- ment, using mis- specified Keynesian form Explicit l} Income multiplier ll} Water availa- and in region exceeded bility would in- Implicit that in other regions. crease average size Assumptions 2. Propensity to con- of farms in project and Beliefs of Test Teams sume locally out of local income=propor- tion of visitor ex- penditure spent locally. 3. National benefits are chiefly local in accrual. 4. Alternative labor opportunities for farmers existed, though they were in other regions. 5. Rate of return on farm capital non- project alternative area and open new farming opportuni- ties there. 2. New farmers would come from contiguous region a rest of nation, causing de- clines in income in these places. 3. All farmers had some alternative. 4. Farm income changes re-spent in fixed proportions. 5. After first round of re-spending, in- come effects could not be attributed to y_preject. 191 TABLE 5 (Continued) Corps of Engineers University of Test Team Wisconsin Test Team Formula and/or Secondary Tertiary aij(ahj); where: Value of sector + sector Multiplier Income income aij = purchases from and industry i per dollar of sales by industry MPC j, a . = value added me . .hJ . in industry 3. acres irrigated - ROunds of~ Infinite One round) Expansion 192 TABLE 6 Estimates of Regional and National Secondary Benefits: Comparison of Rent Model and Approaches Used By Others Regional Secondary National Secondary Benefits ($/year) Benefits ($/Year) Trenton Channel Project MSU Test Team Corps Test Team Rent Model High minus low Mountain Home Project U of Wisc. Test Team Corps Test Team Rent Model High minus low Stonewall Jackson Project Cornell Test Team Corps Test Team Rent Model High minus low Poteau Project Corps Test Team SCS Test Team Rent Model High minus low 1,719,000 135,000,000 2 055 584 W 1,415,000 16,649,000 405 000 Irma-fora 55,000 70,600,000 135 000 W 1,584,000 395,000 200 000 mm 0 0 2 831 000 2,453,000 2,972,000 415 000 275571-000— 137,000 7,080,000 0 :,UEU,UUU 368,000 614,000 240 000 m 193 seen, the estimates vary greatly. The estimates presented by the Test Teams were hurriedly prepared; many of them did not result from the application of the approaches advocated by the respective Test Teams. Thus, the magnitudes are not directly related in all cases to the estimation methods advocated by the teams. Nevertheless, the estimates are of significance, since they give an indication of the rela- tive magnitude of secondary benefits estimates which the reSpective Test Teams would expect to result from their advocated estimation procedures. Trenton Channel Project The Trenton Channel Project has been briefly described above in Chapter V. No additional description will be pre- sented here. The comparative analysis of the Test Team appraisals of the Trenton Channel Project presented herein differs somewhat from that of the other projects. In the dis- cussion which immediately follows, the results from the Rent Model are compared not only to the results from a different approach but also to the results from a slightly different version of the Rent Model. This additional com- parison allows one to appraise the differences in results obtained from two appraisals which are similar in concept but different in coefficients, as opposed to those from two appraisals using essentially different approaches. 194 Michigan State University Test Team The Michigan State University (MSU) Test Team approach to estimating the secondary benefits from the Detroit Tren- ton Channel Project used an earlier version of the model presented in Chapter V of the present study. The earlier version was identical in concept to the present version. Thus, most of the assumptions outlined in Chapter V above also apply to the version used by the MSU Test Team. The greatest difference lay in the treatment of rents stemming- from the increased production of steel. The MSU Test Team used the full value of the resulting output of the Fabri- cated Metals industry in estimating the Wage and Profit Rents stemming-from primary steel production. No other industries were included in the analysis of stemming-from impacts, since steel was a relatively minor input to mOst other industries. Because of the inverse relationship be- tween relative factor cost and traditional stemming-from benefits, the MSU Test Team felt that to include the industries in which steel was a minor input was "to assume the tail wags the dog."1 The application of the earlier version of the model by the MSU Test Team differed also in the direct require- ments coefficients used in estimating the secondary out- puts. Since the 1963 Input-Output Study was not available to the Test Team at the time of its analysis, the coeffi- cients from the 1958 study were used. 195 A third difference between the MSU Test Team version and the present version of the Rent Model lay in the wage rates used in evaluating the alternative earnings of local laborers. The earlier version used national wage rates for both local and national industries, while the present ver- sion used local wage rates in assessing the alternatives to labor in the local industries. The fourth difference between the MSU Test Team pro- cedure and that used in Chapter V herein related to the treatment of Profit Gains. The Test Team used the profits before taxes in estimating the Profit Gains, but then ”rather arbitrarily" reduced the result by one-half to re- flect the recognition that these profits were not "net" in the sense that they could not have been taxed away with- 2 In out causing a reduction in the level of investment. fact the "rather arbitrary" reduction of before-tax profits by 50 per cent was no more arbitrary than the acceptance of the after-tax profit rate used in Chapter V herein. The fact that the results are relatively close (Table 1) is probably due in greatest part to the 48 per cent rate at which corporate profits are taxed. Consequently, there is little difference in the results obtained from the Rent Model under the two different conventions for dealing with profits. The absolute difference between the results obtained from the two versions of the Rent Model appear large 196 (Table 6). However, when compared to the differences which obtain between analyses based upon differing approaches in ensuing sections of the present chapter. The differences obtained from the two versions of the Rent Model are rela- tively small. While the differences between coefficients in the two versions caused some difference in the final estimates obtained, those differences are not so large as the potential differences obtainable when differing bene- fit parameters are being estimated -- e.g., gross activity generated as opposed to employment in the "non-basic" sectors. Much larger differences are obtained when the basic assumptions differ between analyses -- e.g., those relating to the alternative cost of the factors affected and to the creditablity of ensuing rounds of expansion. The MSU Test Team differed from the other test teams in the treatment of the source of funds for financing the project. The MSU Test Team argued that the taxing and spending decisions of the Federal government should not be treated as separate and independent acts, not even from the local standpoint. The process of building a Corps of Engineers project in the Detroit area required that taxes be collected to finance the project. The MSU Test Team pointed out that project regions typically view the project expenditures as "new money" in the region: In the aggre- gate, such cannot be the case, however, since each new project increases taxes in all regions. The MSU Test Team was arguing that at least some of the indirect effects of 197 project expenditures would have occurred in the region any- way, had money not been taxed away from the region to help build the project. When all projects are viewed together, the aggregate demand effect simply reduces to the balanced budget effect, which is a much smaller change than that suggested by the sum of each project treated in isolation. Corps of Engineers Test Team The Trenton Channel Project constituted a Special case of secondary benefit evaluation. The Detroit metro- politan area was characterized by a low unemployment rate and a high level of average income at the time of the test team reports. The Corps of Engineers Trenton Channel (CETC) Test Team pointed out that the major economic problem in the area was the cyclical nature of employment and income because of the high proportion of durable goods manufacturing.3 While average wages in these industries tended to be much above the national average, employment in these industries was highly sensitive to overall changes in the economy. It was pointed out that diversification of the economy to achieve more stable employment was difficult because the high wages paid by the automobile industry and related industries tended to keep out the less cyclical in- dustries which tended to pay generally lower average wages. The expansion of the McLouth steel plant, which would be made possible by the project, was not seen as having a stabilizing effect upon the local economy. 198 The expansion of the McLouth steel plant would be the generator of most of the benefits of the project, since it could not be proven that other firms would use the channel. Thus, the employment effects resulting from the steel mill expansion constituted the basis for the estimated secondary benefits. The primary employment impact would be an increase of 3,000 workers at the steel plant. The test team postu- lated the effeCts of this additional employment on the local economy by assuming an employment base multiplier of 3.0 -- i.e., a ratio of "primary" to "residentiary" employment of 1.0:2.0. Thus, 6,000 additional jobs in the services sector would be created. The CETC Test Team also postulated that stemming-from effects would be realized in the metal fabricating industry leading to the employ- ment of an additional 1,500 workers in that industry. The team assumed that one-half of the McLouth company's out- put would go to metal fabricators, while the other half would go to the automobile industry. That part going to the automobile industry would have no local stemming-from impact on employment, since the steel would have otherwise been bought elsewhere and the same level of local employment would have occurred. The stemming-from employment effects would also have an effect upon local "residentiary" employment. The employment multiplier of 3.0 was applied to the 1,500 jobs created in Metal Fabricating, indicating an additional 199 3,000 jobs in the service industry. Thus, the total employ- ment effects postulated for the region were 4,500 industrial jobs and 9,000 service sector jobs. Since the Detroit metropolitan area did not have a pool of idle labor, the team concluded that these jobs would be largely filled by migrants from other regions. Assuming a laborer-dependency ratio for the industrial sector of l.0:3.0 and for the "residentiary” sector of l.0:2.0 (since half of these employees would be female), the team estimated that regional population would increase by 22,500 persons. The CETC Test Team concluded that the overall effect of the project "would be to increase employment and pOpula- tion in the Detroit area at the expense of other regions but to the overall benefit of the nation."4 This conclu- sion could not have been derived solely from the data presented. There were involved some assumptions regarding the relative welfare of the prospective migrants in their community of origin versus their community of destination, the Detroit area. The test team spoke of "regions" as the bearers of benefits and costs rather than people as the bearers. Thus, it was not clear whether the test team was referring to the migrants alone, or all of the people of the areas involved. Their statement would imply that the "collective good" of the Detroit area would increase, while that of the other regions would decline. Perhaps the ambiguities surrounding the problem of evaluating real 200 welfare under changing conditions of pOpulation density, related social anomie, etc., should not be treated herein, though the test team made some sweeping judgements regard- ing these factors in coming to its conclusion. Assuming that the test team spoke only of the migrants involved, something more concrete can be said about their assumptions regarding the net income effects of the project. Osten— sibly, all of the laborers attracted to the Detroit area would have been earning lower wages in their regions of origin. Thus, overall national efficiency would be en- hanced by reallocating these resources to more productive employment. The regions from which they came would be made worse off by the loss of these laborers. One could surmise that the disbenefit would arise largely from the associated decline in regional production and the taxes thereon. The test team seemed to believe that "extensive" economic growth was good, from the vieWpoint of the Detroit region. Extensive growth has been defined previously as an increase in regional employment which occurs without in- creasing the wages of any people already in the region -- i.e., more workers at the same wage level. In the Trenton Channel case, the new steel manufacturing employment would be complemented by additional service employment according to the existent "basic-non-basic ratio." This is, in reality, extensive growth. Extensive employment growth can be very beneficial to the tax base of economic communities 201 of smaller scale which are struggling to establish viable community services. In the case of a metropolis such as Detroit, however, it would appear that limited scale is no longer a problem. Indeed, the problem with the provision of these services in Detroit may well be that diminishing returns to scale will occur with continued extensive growth. The test team apparently viewed the employment stimu- lated by the project as "intensive growth" from the national vieWpoint -- i.e., growth in which average re- turns to labor rise. Such would be the case if a more "efficient" allocation of labor occurred by the shift to employment in the higher-wage Detroit area. If such were the case, then greater ambiguity is made apparent in the test team's reference to the relative welfare of "regions." Ostensibly, the migrants will have been made marginally better off by this change in residence and employment. However, their region of origin has supposedly been made worse off. But, using regional delineations for benefit assignment, should the before-project or the after-project populace be used as the basis for comparison? It is not made clear which is used by the test team. It does make a difference for the analyst's ultimate concern should be for human welfare and not for some ill-defined regional entity. 202 Stonewall Jackson Reservoir The Stonewall Jackson Reservoir is a proposed Corps of Engineers Project on the West Fork River in northern West Virginia. The project area is located in Appalachia. The project itself, as it was initially designed, is pri- marily a flood control project with some water supply, recreation and water quality (low flow augmentation) aspects. Hydro-electric power production from this project was found to be infeasible. The first cost of the project was estimated to be $33,954,000 in July 1964 prices. The annual operation maintenance and replacement costs were estimated at $164,000, at the same price level. The principal industries in the project area are coal mining, glass manufacturing, and livestock production. The area produces about 20 per cent of the total output of both coal and agricultural products of the state of West Vir- ginia. Nevertheless, population out-migration rates have been very high; and, for all except perhaps the last decade of the past thirty years, out-migration rates have exceeded birth-rates, leading to a decreasing population. Largely as a result of this out-migration, unemployment rates have slowly declined from very high levels toward (but not yet reaching) the national average. Average wages in the area are nearly 20 per cent lower than national average wages. The project area is located in Appalachia and, thus, qualifies for the consideration of redevelopment benefits. 203 As a result, one would expect an extensive analysis of the secondary impacts of the project. However, very little was said about such impacts in the initial project report, and little more has been added by the two test teams in their analyses. Nevertheless, the two test teams do make ex- plicit statements concerning the evaluation of secondary benefits for the project which serve to illucidate their stances and which allow for an evaluation of their basic assumptions and presumptions regarding them. Corps of Epgineers Test Team The Corps of Engineers Test Team which applied the proposed new evaluation procedures to the Stonewall Jackson Project (CESJ Test Team) was composed of Corps of Engi- neers personnel from the Ohio River Division and the Pitts- burgh District Offices. Thus, the same offices were in- volved in producing the CESJ Test Team Report5 as were in- volved in producing the original Project Report. Therefore, in applying the new procedures the test team had the added advantage of familiarity with the project. Because secondary benefits were not evaluated in the original Project Report on the Stonewall Jackson Reservoir, the CESJ Test Team did not have the advantage of having had data collected for that purpose. The test team indica- ted that the time limitations were such that they were un- able to provide any new data for the test evaluation. Thus, all of the analysis of secondary effects was hypothetical. 204 The CESJ Test Team began their discussion by stating their concept of secondary benefits. The benefits from "regional economic development" would consist of wages, salaries and profits from investments that would be "wholly or in part induced to locate in the project area." It was pointed out that, insofar as these might have been located elsewhere in the absence of the project, the total was not net to the nation as a whole, though it would be to the region. However, if the resources which were employed as a result of the investment locating in the project area would have been unemployed otherwise, then the wages and salaries would be net benefits to the nation as a whole.6 Though the CESJ Test Team did not point out the reasoning behind this conclusion, the implicit assumption is that the opportunities available to the resources which would have been employed in the other region in which the investment would occur in the absence of the project were exactly equal to the factor payments which the foregone investment would have made, while the alternatives in the project area were assumed to be valued at zero. Thus, the investment must have been attracted away from another region which had perfectly functioning factor markets and into a region in which no effective demand existed for the resources which the investment employed. The CESJ Test Team saw the basic effects upon employ- ment as occurring via the construction, operation and main- tenance of the project and via the provision of flat, 205 flood-free land for commercial and industrial development. They foresaw additional employment resulting from the de- mands imposed by recreation users of the lake for gasoline, restaurant and motel facilities. The test team believed water supply provision to bear insufficient inducement to attract industrial location and felt that the greatest potential for regional employment generation lay in the provision by the project of flood-free plant sites. Because the Project Report on the Stonewall Jackson Reservoir had not included an analysis of the employment effects via investment attraction, the test team was unable to say how much of an attraction to new investment would be created by the project and how much of an effect upon local employment the project would have. Nevertheless, a hypothetical rule-of-thumb analysis of the benefits from such effects was presented. The test team used a variant of the method develOped by Spindletop Research Center7 to estimate the number of potential jobs resulting from the creation of flood-free industrial sites. The average number of employees per acre in existent plants in the area was determined and multiplied by the acreage of suitable plant sites created by the project. This gave an estimate of the potential new industrial jobs. The average wages and salaries paid in these jobs would then be multiplied by the number of new jobs to determine the total of the new income created by the potential plant locations. The most likely industries 206 to locate on these sites were judged to be apparels and electrical machinery manufacturing. This was concluded from information contained in the economic base study of the Ohio River Basin Comprehensive Survey. The average of wages paid in the two industries was taken as the relevant wage for use in estimating the total potential in- come change. Then, it was suggested that a multiplier of 2.0 be used in estimating the associated change in service sector employment and income. The multiplier was taken from studies of the Appalachian area by Robert R. Nathan Associates, Incorporated, and Spindletop Research Center. The total would yield an estimate of the regional develop- ment benefits. However, only that part of the total which would accrue to unemployed resources were viewed as national gains. Since the out-migration experienced in the area in previous decades had also decreased the unemployment rate, it was concluded that unemployment in the area would even- tually equal the national rate of unemployment. Trend analysis indicated that this would occur around the year 2000. Thus, unemployment benefits could only be claimed for that portion which in the absence of the project would not have out-migrated and found employment in other areas. For test evaluation purposes it was assumed that the project would reduce the rate of unemployment in the area to the national average rate by the year 1975. Those employed by the project in 1975 would be accounted for in the national 207 account. However, diminishing proportions of those em- ployed would be included in the national account for ensu- ing years, and for the year 2000. and thereafter none would be included. The CESJ Test Team was perhaps the most skeptical of all the Federal agency test teams regarding the nature and existence of secondary benefits for the project which they were evaluating. Perhaps this was due to the nature of the project and the area in which it was located. The project had no irrigation nor hydro-electric capacity built in. These are the most easily evaluated aspects of a project so far as secondary income creation is concerned, since they are both directly used as production inputs and often are the limiting factors of output expansion. In most cases the users of these project outputs are already located in the area or are planning to do so pending their provision. However, in the Stonewall Jackson Reservoir case, the other factors were not obviously ready and wait- ing for the project outputs, and the outputs were not so obviously strategic to any foreseeable production process. These factors might have been instrumental in eliciting the warning which the test team voiced regarding the credit for expansion benefits. In essence, they warned against the "one factor theory" of production in saying that credit for any expansion benefits would be in part due to the new interstate highway system and the Appalachian corridors, as well as other associated investment expenditures. Thus, 208 while the provision of flood free land was seen as impor- tant to the develOpment process, the test team felt that all of the benefits from economic expansion should not be assigned to the provision of flood control and urged that an attempt be made to develop a method for determining the proportion which should be assigned to each contributing factor. The test team felt that underemployment was a "rea- sonable simple concept" but that it was "very difficult to measure." However, an attempt was made to measure the ex- tent of underemployment in the area. "Per capita income was used as a proxy measure in which the Clarksburg Economic Area was compared to the United States average."8 The percentage difference was taken as the measure of under- employment. The reasons for using per capita income rather than average wages or some other labor-based unit were not given; neither was the "reasonably simple concept" of underemployment held by the test team stipulated. However, a recognition on the part of the test team of the part played by educational and attitudinal factors in develOp- ment was indicated in another section of the report. Thus, the test team must have believed that even in perfectly functioning markets the (short run) average wages for the Appalachian laborers would have been lower than the average for the rest of the nation. Therefore, the income problem was not simply one of demand deficiency but also one of resource productivity; the latter was probably instrumental 209 in causing the former. As a result, the test team tended to under-emphasize the income producing effect of the aggre- gate demand changes occasioned by construction, operation and maintenance expenditures. Whether this was due to a belief on their part that few local laborers would be em- ployed and that most project-induced spending would occur elsewhere, or whether it was due to a down-playing of the effects of aggregate demand changes on local income could not be determined. Nevertheless, it was apparent that the test team gave little consideration to the aggregate demand effects of the project-related expenditures on the area. There was some inconsistency on the part of the test team in that a relatively large multiplier was accepted in evaluating the secondary income producing effects of employ- ment opportunities created by flood-free site provision, while little was said about the secondary effects of con- struction, Operation and maintenance of the project. The discrepancy in treatment must have been due to an oversight rather than a belief that the multiplier effects would have been 2.0 and zero, respectively. An economic base multiplier of 2.0 was accepted as the relevant measure of the secondary income producing effects of new plant employment in the area. In using such a multiplier to estimate secondary benefits several assump- tions must be made. First, it must be assumed that the relationship between "basic" employment and income and "non- basic" employment and income in the area will remain 210 approximately the same as area income increases. Whether or not this would be true for such a region as Appalachia is perhaps debatable. Secondly, it must be assumed that those employed in non-basic activities because of the multi— plier effects of the new basic employment.would not have been employed otherwise, and that their forced leisure was of zero value to them. Thirdly, if the secondary benefits are to be net to the nation, it must be assumed that the other region in which the plant would have located was ex- periencing full employment and perfect factor market opera- tion. Cornell Universipy Test Team The Cornell University (CU) Test Team Report discus- sed both the economies of scale type of secondary benefits and the conventional variety of secondary benefits. How- ever, the test team preferred to view the former as a variety of "national efficiency benefits." Only those changes in income which occurred through the multiplier effects of the project were viewed as secondary benefits. While the test team believed that net secondary (multiplier) benefits could prevail at the national level, it was de- cided that the multiplier impacts would be evaluated only in the Regional Income Account of the project analysis, and it was suggested that any adverse effects upon other regions should be analyzed and discussed therein as well.9 211 The CU Test Team was very dubious of the analysis of secondary effects under the "use externalities" definition provided by the Task Force. They were particularly con- cerned about the imputation of causation for the increased outputs to water services, ". . . in view of the essentially permissive nature of water resources in the regional growth process. . ." Thus, they felt that the evaluation of such effects should be included ". . . only if a strong and prior case can be made that shortage of water services act as a constraint on more optimal production or that a water project will bring about technological change." Like the Corps of Engineers Test Team the Cornell University Test Team felt that too many other factors were ". . . required at predetermined levels (water is usually not) to be able to ascribe reduced labor unemployment solely or partially to the effect of water development on industry growth." Thus, the test team recommended that ". . . both of the approaches, suggested by the Task Force, to measure 'national income secondary benefits' he rejected in the case where a proposed project is assumed to have impacts on labor unemployment and immobility through expansion of industries directly or indirectly using project outputs."10 The reasons for the suggested rejection were delineated as 1) the inability to separate joint effects, 2) the permis- sive role of water in growth, 3) the possibility of technical substitution, and 4) the uncertainty involved in forecasting human resource immobilities. 212 The CU Test Team expressed similar beliefs to those expressed by the MSU Test Team regarding the credit for economic expansion. The MSU Test Team felt that some credit should be given to the water project, though they could not say how much. The MSU Test Team gave credit for only the first round of expansion. The position of the CU Test Team was that me credit should be assigned to the water project. This extreme position is justifiable only by negating the projects primary benefits, which depended largely upon the development of flood-free industrial sites. The CU Test Team position on the indirect project impacts indi- cates that the test team did not believe that the primary project benefits from site creation would materialize. The CU Test Team felt that indirect impacts upon the region from recreation development were a distinct possi- bility. Thus, their approach in dealing with recreation impacts was different from that dealing with flood control. It was felt that a multiplier analysis of recreation ex- penditures could be carried out, since recreation develop- ment was likely to occur. However, these impacts should be limited to the regional account. It was suggested that secondary (multiplier) benefits of a project only be included in the national income effects account for the impact on long run unemployed labor put to work by the expenditure of funds for construction, operation and maintenance. No other effects should be included, be- cause of the uncertainty involved in predicting long range 213 resource immobilities and the expansionary effects of proj- ect outputs on other sectors. Furthermore, in calculating the multiplier effects of the project expenditures, care should be taken to determine the origin of the resources employed. Even though unemployment rates might be high in the project region, the expansionary effect would not constitute real net benefits if workers were drawn from other employment in other regions. The test team felt that the relevant measure of secondary benefits was the growth in per capita income rather than gross regional income or product. Thus, "extensive" growth would not constitute a real secondary benefit to the region. However, since one could easily estimate the per capita measure from the total, it was suggested that gross income estimating procedures were permissable as means of getting at the secondary benefit estimates. The position of the CU Test Team regarding intensive growth as the measure of regional development is similar to the position taken in the present study. The Rent Model is an attempt to operationalize the concept of intensive growth through its emphasis upon changes in income to pre- viously employed laborers. Similar positions were taken by the MSU Test Team and the University of Wisconsin (UWMH) Test Team. Like many of the other test teams, the Cornell Uni- versity Test Team appeared a bit contradictory in their 214 efforts to separate the national efficiency benefits, the national secondary benefits, and the regional secondary benefits. Part of the confusion perhaps was caused by their attempt to consider secondary benefits only in the regional income account -- as they interpreted the Task Force Report to suggest -- while they believed that under certain conditions net national secondary benefits could occur as well. Additionally, the attempt to categorize the project effects into "national efficiency" accounts and "regional income" accounts rather than primary and second- ary benefits also seemed to add to the confusion. In large part, this latter confusion appeared to stem from the fail- ure to distinguish adequately between regional income changes due to inter-regional pecuniary effects and those due to net national secondary changes in output which were localized in the region. The same difficulty was had by other test teams. The test team was skeptical of the analysis of secondary benefits at the national level due to under- employment. They felt that under-employment was a very poorly defined concept and that there was ". . . no re- source that cannot be put to some 'higher use' given ef- fective demand." Thus, they recommended that only employ- ment benefits for unemployed leper be included in the ”national efficiency account." It was considered permis- sable to include the evaluation of benefits from under- employed labor in the regional income account, however, 215 since presumably one should include pecuniary effects as well in that account.11 Again, the CU Test Team position is somewhat extreme regarding benefits to "under-employed" labor. It is pos- sible for laborers to achieve "higher" employment without the changes being purely pecuniary. The conditions under which such might be the case are perhaps also extreme, but they nevertheless exist. For example, it is quite possible that increased availability of a water service might markedly increase the marginal physical product of labor, particularly if the two were complementary inputs. In the case of irrigation water provision, there is good reason to expect such complementarity. In the extreme case, if labor were perfectly inelastic in supply and the product being produced were perfectly elastic in demand, much of the increase in value produced would redound to labor in the form of "rent." The price of the product would not change. Purchases of other goods need not de- cline, since the income generated would be sufficient to purchase the increased output. Pecuniary ramifications could be minimized by invoking monetary policy to increase the nominal money supply equivalent to the change in output. The CU Test Team position regarding changes in wages to labor failed to consider both parameters of the derived demand for labor. The CU Test Team dealt only with the Keynesian induced demand effects upon the demand for prod- ucts, which tend to be largely pecuniary in nature. The 216 demand for a factor of production depends also upon its physical productivity, however, and resource demand changes which occur through changes in physical productivity need not be wholly pecuniary. The test team was very cognizant of the secondary bene- fit limitations posed by supply inelasticities, especially that relating to the supply of labor. In essence, labor was treated as the critical factor in the aggregate production function. The assumption made by the test team regarding the aggregate supply function (via the labor supply function) were made explicit throughout the analysis of secondary bene- fits. Moreover, an attempt was made to adjust the secondary employment effects for the probability that not all of the increased labor income would accrue to previously unem- ployed laborers. The estimates of the multiplier effects of recreation expenditures, for example, were cut in half to reflect this belief. By interpreting the instructions from the Task Force in such a manner as to limit the consideration of secondary benefits to the regional viewpoint, the test team, unlike the MSU Test Team, circumvented the necessity of overtly specifying (or implicitly assuming) the fiscal conditions under which their analysis would be relevant. Except for the fact that a small portion of the tax-financed cost of the project would have come from the area, it would make little difference from the regional vieWpoint how the project was financed. From the national vieWpoint, how- ever, it would make a difference; and the acceptance of 217 the Task Force instructions constituted an implicit accept- ance of the assumptions which underlay them. By evaluating only the secondary impacts accruing to the project region they implied that either 1) the costs to other regions and the nation as a whole were irrelevant either because they were presumably small or because great value was placed upon the stimulation of secondary benefits in the project region, or 2) it was assumed that there were no secondary impacts (either positive or negative) upon other regions and that the project financing did not cause other employ- ment opportunities to contract. The test team did amel- iorate this implied position somewhat by suggeSting that the regional account should also show the effects upon other regions. In suggesting the exclusion from regional secondary benefit calculation of those laborers who came from outside of the region, the test team by implication assumed that either 1) the laborers were earning equivalent wages before migrating, or 2) the process of regional population growth had an equivalent welfare decreasing effect upon the pre— vious residents of the region. In a perfectly competitive setting (and ignoring the spatial aspects) the former would be logically acceptable; however, if sufficient market im- perfections existed to cause unemployment (or under- . employment) in the region, it is possible that the adjust- ments through migration were non-marginal to the laborers involved. In the case of the latter, the test team might 218 have harbored such a belief, though in no place in their report did they make it explicit. In summary, the CU Test Team accepted a fairly re- strictive definition of secondary benefits. Only the multiplier impacts were considered "indirect." Their consideration was limited to the regional account. More- over, project effects upon resource productivity were con- sidered to belong in the "national efficiency account." The multiplier effects of project construction expenditures were considered to contribute to regional secondary bene- fits. Secondary effects from project outputs were con- sidered to be too uncertain and/or not sufficiently causally-linked to the project to justify their inclusion as regional or national benefits, even in the presence of unemployment. Thus, all stemming-from benefits were ex- cluded from the analysis, and much of the induced-by effects were omitted (the exception being those induced by project construction). Changes in the employment of labor which lead to higher regional per capita income were seen as the relevant measure of secondary benefits. Direct effects upon enemployed labor were seen as belonging in the national efficiency account, while indirect effects upon unemployment were seen as belonging in the regional (secondary) income account . 219 Poteau Watershed Project The Poteau Watershed Project was constructed by the Soil Conservation Service Of the United States Department of Agriculture. The basic work plan provided for (a) land treatment measures to reduce flooding, sedimentation, and erosion, (b) 17 floodwater retardation structures (c) one multi-purpose structure for flood control and water supply, (d) 10 miles of channel improvement. The area to be ef- fected by the project consisted of Scott County, Arkansas, and Le Flore County, Oklahoma. The project area was classified as economically depressed and qualified for the consideration of redevelopment benefits. The most certain of the anticipated redevelopment effects of the project were to come from the employment effects generated by the increased output of a poultry processing plant. The increased output was to be made possible by the provision of additional water supply by the project. Additional income and employment effects were to come from increased eXpenditures for recreation in the area by thoseliving outside of the area. The original evaluation of the project by the Soil Conservation Service (SCS) included, in essence, two cate- gories of secondary benefits. First, their consideration of redevelopment benefits in the form of increased wages and salaries to those previously unemployed workers who would be employed as a result of construction and operation and maintenance of the project constituted one form of 220 secondary benefit. Also, the increased employment due to the industrial water supply effects were placed in the same category. Secondly, the SCS increased their primary bene- fits by 10 per cent and described the addition as "secondary effects" of the project. The 10 per cent adjustment could be called a "multiplier" effect. Multipliers are normally applied to some exogenous change in income or employment, or whatever is being evaluated. Unless all Of the primary benefits come in the form of exogenous changes in income, the effective multiplier used by the SCS is not 1.10, though there is implicit in the procedure used some sub- scription to the multiplier concept. Cqmps of Emgineers Test Team A test team made up of staff members from the South- western Division and the Tulsa District Offices of the Corps of Engineers (CEP Test Team) comprised one of the units which tested the prOposed new evaluation procedures upon the Poteau Watershed Project. The CEP Test Team did not attempt a primary research effort to evaluate the secondary impacts of the project. However, they did present some very definite ideas about how such evaluation should be done.12 The CEP Test Team agreed in principle to the in- clusion of the entire wages and salaries of the workers employed by the processing plant as project benefits. However, the team felt that the inclusion of the direct 221 change in wages alone was incomplete: The multiplier ef- fects of those changes should also be included. In addi- tion, the team felt that the proper measure of the recrea- tion benefits of the project was the change in area income directly and indirectly stimulated by expenditures for recreation. The multiplier effects of the increased poultry plant employment were called "redevelopment bene- fits." The economic effects of the recreatiOn expenditures, it appeared, were intended to represent the principal quantitative measure of the recreation benefits. The term "secondary benefits" was used only in referring to the multiplier effects. The employment effects, such as those felt by the poultry processing em- ployees, were included in the primary benefit account. The secondary benefits were computed as the multiplier effects of these and other primary benefits. Secondary benefits were computed for both the National Income Account and the Regional Income Account. The argument for including them in the National Account was two-fold. First, there was the existence of unemployed and under-employed labor in the project area. Thus, it was argued, resources put to use in the area represented real gains to the nation as a whole. Second, the argument was made that ". . . the de- cision to develop one region of the country at the expense of another contains inherent equity and regional considera- tions, in terms of both income distribution and population dispersal, which offset the opportunities foregone" (in 222 13 The first of these reasons would appear other regions). to be more amenable to economic analysis than the second. The team was cognizant of the part played by aggre- gate supply in determining the real income multiplier effects. They discussed the existence of unemployment in the area and the effect this unemployment would have upon the net national income effects of industrial expansion in the area. Moreover, they felt that increases in per capita income,"after allowance for inflation," was the proper measure of progress. Thus, they recognized both the problem of aggregate supply elasticity and that of "intensive" regional growth. That is, they viewed the in- come issue as one of not merely increasing the gross product of the region by job and worker migration, but of increas- ing the real incomes of those already residing in the area. In so far as there were unemployed and under-employed workers in the area, it was possible to increase area in- comes without causing a decline in incomes in another area. The team felt that an income multiplier, "based on the marginal propensity to consume," should be derived for the area. The team was unable to derive such a multiplier in the time allotted for the test, it was pointed out. However, the team was confident that a reasonably accurate multiplier could be developed from secondary data. The use of an input-output study was mentioned, but it was con- sidered to be too expensive. For purposes of illustration, a multiplier of 1.65 was accepted for the test. The 223 multiplier was drawn from a recent economic base study done by the Department of Labor which indicated that ". . . pro- viding 100 jobs in manufacturing would create 65 additional jobs in other segments of the economy."14 This multiplier was applied to the income changes occasioned by the expan- sion of the poultry processing plant. However, some in- consistency in their approach resulted from its use, since the economic base multiplier is an extensive growth multi- plier, while the team felt that real growth resulted only from intensive changes in income. The team felt that multiplier should be estimated for all project areas. They mentioned some possible means by which these estimates might be made: "An input-output study, a study of published data, a historic study of com- pleted projects, field work, or any combination which will produce the most reliable result.” "Historic study" apparently refers to the comparative projection technique. The team apparently believed that each of these approaches would yield comparable multipliers. The team considered both unemployment and under- employment to be problems in the Poteau project area. Thus, they believed that the multiplier effects of increases in the level of regional aggregate demand would be beneficial to the area. However, in discussing the evaluation of the multiplier impacts, the team made no distinction between the evaluation of the impacts upon the two groups. The opportunity costs in both cases were assumed to be zero. 224 As was pointed out in preceding sections, only in very limited circumstances would the alternatives be valued at zero even for those totally unemployed. Certainly, in the case of the under-employed one should not value the alter- native at zero. The team included the increased profits from the poultry processing operation in the evaluation of project benefits. They did not describe them as "secondary" benefits, however. It was their belief that the profits constituted primary benefits of the project. In evaluating the secondary project effects, these profits were not treated in the same manner as were the wages and salaries, however. The multiplier was not applied to the increased profits. Consistency would dictate that wages, salaries, and profits be treated alike in this instance: Ostensibly, all are exogenous increases in area income, and the second round effects of the expenditure Of that income should be similar. However, if the persons to whom the profits accrued were not area residents, the exclusion of the secondary effects of the profits from the regional account would be appropriate. If unemployment existed in the area in which the profits would finally be re-spent, then the secondary effects would accrue in the national account, though not in the regional account. In summary, the team was cognizant of the role played by unemployed labor and resultant supply elasticities in determining the extent of real changes in national income 225 caused by regional changes in aggregate demand.. Further- more, the team viewed changes in regional employment which drew labor from outside the area as having possible dele- terious effects upon other regions. They believed that net secondary benefits could occur nationally as well as locally, however, if unemployment existed in the project area. It was the viewpoint of the team that regional in- come considerations should prevail, since the Water Re- source Council had allegedly made population re-dispersion an overt objective of the water resources program. Thus, secondary income effects at the local level should be the factor evaluated. This, in effect, constituted an implicit assumption that the marginal utility of income in the proj- ect region was greater than that of the nation as a whole. Soil Conservation Service Test Team The Soil Conservation Service Test Team (SCSP Test Team) and the other teams which tested the proposed pro- cedures on the Poteau Watershed Project had some advantages over the other teams involved in the testing in dealing with the "expansionary" effects of the project. The poultry processing plant which was a major direct bene- ficiary of project water had already begun to receive the increased water supply and had expanded operations as a result. Thus, "The Test Team found the data available exceeded that which would normally be available. For exam- ple, there was an existing industry having unused capacity 226 within the project and it was obvious that lack of water was the bottleneck for expansion. In addition data was avail- able for effects after the bottleneck was eliminated."15 As a result of these factors, the SCSP Test Team was able to estimate, with an unusual amount of certainty, the ef- fects of the project upon employment via the elimination of a production bottleneck. The case of a food processing plant provides an excellent example of the bottleneck thesis as it relates to the water resource program. In the processing of most foods, water is a strategic factor of production. Its presence or absence strongly influences the location of food processing plants, and its degree of abundance limits the extent to which those plants can expand. This indus- try is somewhat unusual in its degree of dependence upon water. The "bottleneck clause" in the Task Force Report is most strongly supported by the food processing example. The case of the poultry processing plant fits the bottleneck thesis so well that both the original evaluation of the Poteau Watershed Project and the SCSP Test Team Report considered the expansionary effects upon the wages, salaries and profits from the poultry processing plant as primary (direct) project benefits. These effects were classified as "redevelopment benefits" and were grouped with the wages paid to otherwise-unemployed individuals who were employed as a result of construction, operation and main- tenance of the project. This group of benefits, in essence, 227 was composed of the "first round effects" of the project upon local unemployed. The second and later round effects of the project upon exogenous demand were classified as secondary benefits and were treated separately from the "redevelopment benefits." The secondary benefits consisted of the multiplier effects of the increases in exogenous income to the region result- ing directly from the project. The exogenous changes were expected to come from 1) per diem expenditures in the region by project construction workers whose primary resi- dence was outside of the region, 2) expenditures by visitors from outside of the region in using the recreation facili- ties provided by the project and, 3) the increased income realized from the change in wages and salaries from the poultry processing operation. The increased profits from the poultry processing plant were included in the national account but not in the regional account, since the owners of the plant resided outside of the region. In evaluating the "expansion benefits" from the above- described exogenous changes in regional demand, the SCS Team selected a multiplier which was based on data prepared by Clinton Russell, Agricultural Economist, SCS, Little Rock, Arkansas. The multiplier had a value of 3.85, which the SCSP Test Team concluded "it appeared that for this portion of Arkansas, the multiplier should be . . ." However, since "a leakage of 80 per cent was considered realistic for this region," the multiplier used in the regional account was 228 lowered to 1.57. The full value of 3.85 was considered to be the relevant multiplier for evaluating changes in the national account, since ". . . the leakage would have a stimulating effect nationally." However, "in the absence of knowledge concerning the gains that could have been made had project resources been used elsewhere," the test team could not make a realistic appraisal of the effect.16 The "redevelopment benefits" of the project were estimated to have the potential effect of employing all idle labor in the region. The SCSP Test Team recognized that no "slack" existed which would allow the multiplier to create net national gains in the region. Thus, the multiplier effects were de facto restricted to the re- gional account, though "expansion benefits" were displayed in brackets in the national account without being included in the benefit-cost ratio. In evaluating the employment effects of the project, the SCS Team assumed that the unemployment rate in the area would have declined to the national average in 20 years in the absence of the project. Thus, the "redeveIOpment benefits" were restricted to the first 20 years of the life of the project. There is implicit in this assumption a "belief" regarding the manner in which the inter-regional reallocation of resources occurs and a "judgement" regard- ing the amount of lag in the market reallocation process that society should tolerate. The SCSP Test Team appar- ently believed that there existed frictions (though not 229 absolute barriers) to the inter-regional flow of resources and that in this case the frictions were such that a 20 year lag would be required for an "efficient" allocation to be achieved. The consideration of redevelopment and secondary benefits indicated that the SCSP Test Team felt that 20 years was too long, in view of the distributional and equity considerations involved. This does not mean, however, that they did not agree with Eckstein and others that price (wage) differentials are the prime movers of a market economy. There is a normative question involved which regards the trade off between maintaining incentives to better allocation of resources and re-dressing the dis- tributive (pecuniary) effects of a market which does not re-allocate resources instantaneously and along a continu- ous function of alternatives, as marginalist theory depicts the process. In evaluating the expansion benefits in the region from the wages received by those who would be employed as a result of the project, the SCSP Test Team subtracted the unemployment compensation payments from the new wages and applied the multiplier to the differential. This was done in recognition of the fact that the unemployment payments constituted exogenous income which would be lost as a result of the employment. More importantly to the present study, however, the deduction for the income foregone in this "first round transaction" constituted a step towards the same deduction for ensuing rounds. 230 In evaluating the expansion benefits from exogenous expenditure for recreation, the SCS Team assumed that each visitor from outside of the region would spend an average of $5.00 per day in the region. It was assumed that the profit rate on these expenditures would be about 20 percent. The multiplier was applied to the profits which accrued to the exogenous recreation expenditures. By applying the multiplier to only the profits from the recreation expenditures, the SCS Test Team eliminated the portion of secondary effects which has been called "induced-by" effects by practitioners in the water re- sources field. As was pointed out in Chapter IV, there is a semantic problem involved in the nomenclature of the dif- ferent multiplier effects. In the water resource field, "induced-by" effects are discussed as those increases in income which occur secondarily as a result of expenditures for inputs required to meet a specified level of production (either assuming or due to a specified level of demand for that production). However, in the Regional Science field and in Macro-economics literature, "induced" effects are discussed as those secondary income effects which result from the respending of income (in the form of wages, salaries and profits) through the household sector. In essence, there exist two practically identical names for the two separate components of the first round dollar. The water resource field's nomenclature applies to the "cost- of-production" component of the exogenous expenditure, 231 while the Regional Science-Macro-economics nomenclature applies to the household re-spending component of incomes earned. In the report, the SCSP Test Team actually used the "household induced" component of the expenditure in applying the multiplier to the recreation expenditure. The convention used by the SCSP Test Team in evalua- ting the secondary benefits from recreation warrants a return to the earlier discussion in the present study re- garding what the multiplier actually is and what it should be used to multiply. In the SCSP Test Team report a multi- plier was adopted which looked to the SCSP Test Team mem- bers like what the multiplier for the area "should be." There was no discussion in their report regarding the kind of multiplier which had been accepted. If the multiplier actually adOpted was a Keynesian (i.e., "household in- duced") multiplier, then the application of that multiplier to the profit component was perhaps the proper application. The adjustment of the multiplier for "leakages" from the region provides an additional point for discussion re- garding the validity of the multiplier. In essence, "the multiplier" provides an estimate of the total volume of income over time that a given exogenous change in demand can sustain. Because of the process by which costs to one factor become returns to another factor, every dollar which is respent becomes income to someone. Thus, the limit to the multiplier is set by the leakages from the stream of respending. These leakages can occur through hoarding of 232 income by parties to the cycle or by "exporting" part of the respending -- i.e., by importing goods and services from outside of the system. Frictions which merely delay the re- spending do not effect the final value of the multiplier, since the process is infinite and timeless (i.e., there is no discounting of the income stream). In essence, all of the income effects are assumed to occur instantaneously, as a result. The multiplier which the SCSP Test Team adOpted and then adjusted for "leakage" must have already been adjusted for some degree of leakage; otherwise its value would have been infinite. The degree to which it had already been adjusted depends upon the kime of multi- plier which was estimated in the first place. In reality, the leakages which occur in an economic system (regional or otherwise) are very difficult to estimate. Furthermore, the difference that "frictions" which delay responding actually make when the element of time is considered can constitute a substantial "quasi-leakage" to the stream. Thus, conventions such as excluding households from the endogenous matrix or other such methods are used to place a limit on the multiplier which is not otherwise provided in a secondary impact study. Often these adjustments offer very rough representation of the recognition that this problem exists. All of this again points up the question voiced in Chapter IV concerning exactly what it is that the multiplier shows. The Haberler argument that the multiplier 233 represents merely a mathematical tautology is relevant to such a discussion. The SCSP Test Team also included the evaluation of an "induced-by" component in estimating the secondary bene- fits of the project. In this instance, they did not use the multiplier to estimate the secondary income effects. Rather, they used ". . . percentage estimates of primary flood prevention and recreation benefits and of the effects of increased costs of producing added goods as induced by the project." They used a figure of 10 per cent to reflect the profits realized at other stages of the production process. The practice in this regard was very similar to that used by the Bureau of Reclamation in estimating "induced-by" benefits. The SCSP Test Team felt that this was an acceptable procedure under the circumstances, since "tracing out the income flows through the economy" would have been ". . . a laborious process and the study was considered too costly for a comparatively small watershed project."17 In essence, they assumed that the "output multipliers" for the sectors affected averaged 1.10. In summary, the SCSP Test Team enjoyed the luxury of some hindsight in their test. They tested the new pro- cedures on a project which provided a classic case of the water service bottleneck thesis. There was substantial evidence that unemployment existed and that the effects of the project upon the unemployed was beneficial. Since, there had been "slack" in the local economy, there were 234 opportunities for net national secondary effects which at the same time could help meet regional growth objectives. The SCSP Test Team made some explicit and implicit judgements about how resource allocation occurs. They be- lieved that the process would require 20 years to rectify the area's unemployment problem, and they judged that 20 years was too long to wait. They used multiplier analysis to estimate the effects of the project in speeding up this readjustment process. The multiplier used appeared to be a Keynesian "induced" multiplier, but no attempt was made to explain its form or its appropriateness. An adjustment was made in the multiplier to account for "leakages" of the effects to outside of the project area. While some adjust- ment of the multiplier which was accepted was perhaps in- dicated by its magnitude, the rule-of-thumb adjustment of an already uncertain figure regenerated earlier questions regarding the meaning and validity of such analysis. Mountain Home Project The Mountain Home Project of the Bureau of Reclamation is primarily an irrigation project. The key feature of the project is the reclamation of the drylands of the Mountain Home Desert, though the project includes other objectives such as electric power production, water supply, flood control, and fish and wildlife enhancement. The primary secondary impact is expected to develop from the irrigation effects, since much of the electric power generated by the 235 project will be used for pumping irrigation water and since the lake is not expected to have a large recreation impact. Project construction cost is estimated at $153,700,000. Corps of Engineers Test Team The Corps of Engineers (CEMH) Test Team which tested the proposed procedures on the Mountain Home Project felt that "no particular problems were raised by the regional develOpment benefit analysis." The team "used income as the measure of the benefits." However, they felt that "more study would be required on multiplier effects of direct expenditures for general application in project . "l8 analySis. The team did nevertheless include multiplier effects in their report. The CEMH Test Team believed that only the income realized by those persons who would have been unemployed in the absence of the project should be included as net national secondary benefits. Their report stated that "if in the absence of the project, comparable employment would exist elsewhere, no labor resource utilization credit 19 While not elaborating upon this nationally is realized." statement, the team appeared to express a viewpoint often encountered in the theoretical literature, but not often expressed by Federal water resource agency personnel. The viewpoint holds that the aggregate demand multiplier ef- fects created by the project are not net to the nation, if the funds to build the project were taxed away from other 236 uses. Thus, the project impacts are not necessarily net national gains, ". . . since equivalent developments un- doubtedly would take place elsewhere in the nation in the 20 absence of the project." "If in the absence of the proj- ect comparable employment would exist elsewhere, no labor resource utilization credit nationally is realized."21 However, the team felt that it was impossible to determine the net employment differences caused by the project. Thus, they felt that nothing could be said with any degree of certainty regarding the net national secondary effects of the project. Nevertheless, the team did include national secondary benefits in their evaluation. They assumed that 20 per cent of those employed by the project would have been otherwise unemployed "anywhere." The Corps Team was insightful in pointing out other "secondary benefits" than those of aggregate demand stimu- lation. These additional benefits consisted of more stable employment, more diversified economic base, in- creased investment and an expansion in job opportunities. The latter two are normally associated with secondary bene- fits and warrant little further discussion. The former two, however, constitute something Of a departure from the general categories of consideration in secondary benefit evaluation. In fact, to a large degree they must be played off against multiplier effects in decisions regarding the prOper development strategy. In general, the local economy which exhibits the greatest input-output linkages (and, 237 hence the highest local inter-industry multipliers) also exhibits the least diversified economic base. This depends, of course, upon the kind of multiplier adopted in the analy- sis. However, the multipliers which allow the greatest disaggregation and have the greatest potential of accurate representation are the input-output multipliers. These clearly tend to force a trade off between diversification and multiplier potential. The CEMH Test Team did not elaborate upon this aspect of the additional group of secondary benefits, however. The CEMH Test Team went furthest in the evaluation of regional develOpment benefits. This was logical, however, since the team believed that "all national income benefits generally accrue to the region in which the project is located or the area of influence for which it is developed." Thus, the benefits in the regional account included all of those in the national account. In addition, the re- gional account included secondary project effects which exceeded those of the nation as a whole. This was true because of the convention adopted by the team whereby only 20 per cent of the employment stimulated in the region was assumed to have been otherwise unemployed "anywhere." In effect, the assumption was made that the real income multi- plier in the project region was greater than that in other adversely effected areas, presumably the rest of the nation. Given the economic base of the project region, it is tenuous to assume that the local multiplier exceeded 238 by the amount postulated the average of those for other localities in the nation. The local income multiplier effects were based upon the direct benefits from irrigation, recreation, and fish and wildlife. The secondary benefits from irrigation were estimated using a local income multiplier developed in a research project at Washington State University on the Columbia Basin Project. The multiplier expressed a rela- tionship between income generated "in the secondary sector (project stemming from effects)" and income generated "in the tertiary sector (project induced by effects)," and the number of acres irrigated. The team believed the multiplier transplant to be justifiable because of similarities be- tween the two areas in terms of economic base, climate, irrigated area, population density, regional markets, and transportation facilities. However, since the elevation of the project areas was 1,500 feet greater than the Columbia Basin area, the multiplier was adjusted downward 'by 10 per cent. Whether or not the adjustment was appro- priate is a question which could not be answered without a great deal of research. Thus, little more can be said herein than to comment that the transplant has all of the inherent problems discussed in Chapter II above, and that the amount of study required to adequately justify and adjust a proper multiplier transplant is probably not greatly different from that required to construct a local multiplier firstjhand. 239 In estimating the secondary benefits from recreation and from fish and wildlife develOpment, a different ap- proach was used. The team developed a multiplier from data on expenditures by visitors from outside of the project areas of several projects. The data which were used re- lated to average expenditures per visitor per day and the proportion of that expenditure which accrued to the project area. Total expenditures were obtained by multiplying per person expenditures by the estimated number of visitors from outside the project area expected each year. The multiplier was developed using the generalized Keynesian form and was somewhat analogous to the simple economic base multiplier, the numerator consisting of the proportion of total expenditures by outsiders which accrue locally and the denominator consisting of one minus the proportion of total expenditures by outsiders which accrue locally. The difficulty, however, is that both the numerator and denominator are badly mis-specified. The team explicitly assumes that the propensity to consume locally out of local income is identical to the proportion of visitation expenditures spent locally. Obviously, there is no a priori reason to assume this to be the case, and there is no basis in theory for linking the two ratios. Actually, what has been done is to define an income flow from the recreation user to the local area and back to the recreation user in the same proportion, then back to the local area again, etc., ad infinitum. Neither of the above 240 two cases is very realistic. The former would provide the more acceptable alternative, if it could be demonstrated empirically that the marginal propencity to consume 10- cally were equal to the proportion of visitation eXpendi- tures accruing locally. An additional point which can be made at this juncture relates to the multiplicand of the multiplier generated by the Corps Team. The expenditure proportions which are used relate to gross income to those who provide the goods and services to the visitors. Thus, notwithstanding the mis- specification of ensuing rounds in the team's multiplier, the first round of local income accrual is mis-specified. In evaluating the direct benefits, the team was very diligent in attempting to determine the real costs and returns to fixed factors which would be employed as a re- sult of the project. The distinction between regional and national benefits forced them to effectuate certain assump- tions and beliefs regarding regional and inter-regional resource mobilities. These same assumptions and beliefs then came into play as the team evaluated the secondary impacts of the project. The CEMH Test Team felt that a reasonable return to the farm operators' labor should be included as a cost item in the farm budgets (contrary to Bureau of Reclamation Practice). They believed that to do otherwise was to as- Stune that, in the absence of the project, the farmer would lulve been totally unemployed. To adjust for this omission, 241 they adjusted the net farm income downward by one half. This reflected their belief that the increased irrigation water would cause a better utilization of the farmer Opera- tors managerial ability. The productivity which would be lost was a cost of the project. However, the team included it as a cost only in accounting for the national income benefits. In the regional account the alternative cost of the farm operators, labor was not included. ‘The differ- entiation between the two accounts is justifiable only under certain conditions. If the farm operator in question were employed at a lower level in some other part of the country and moved to a project farm and realized a higher income, then the team's convention was perhaps correct. (Other similar resource movements could have the same net effect). Only under such restrictive conditions would the alternative costs not be felt in the project region as well. Consider- ing the migration pattern for the region, the direction of resource flow required to make the team's accounting correct is not the flow which one would normally predict. Return to farm capital was treated in similar fashion to farm Operator's labor. It was deducted as a production cost in the national account, while it was treated as a ‘benefit in the regional account. The only conditions which might justify this distinction would be a zero rate of return on capital in all non-project alternatives in the IYBgion, while the rate of return in the rest of the nation “His equal to the rate of return on capital invested in 242 project farms. Such a situation is unlikely. Ordinarily one would include normal returns to capital as a benefit only when the capital was already sunk and not transferable. Then any benefits to its employment should be included in both accounts. The treatment of farm labor income was analogous to that of farm Operator's income. Fifteen per cent of farm labor income was assumed to go to unemployed'farm labor and hence was treated as a benefit in the national account, while all of the wages were included in the regional account as benefits. One possible justification for this distinction would be a belief or an assumption that 85 per cent of those laborers would be mobile between regions (during the period of project effectiveness) and would migrate to the jobs which would have existed in other re- gions in the absence of the project. This, obviously, would constitute a "slippage" of 15 per cent in the resource adjustment process. Thus, the team seems to question the instantaneous adjustment process of micro-economic theory. The team also evaluated the secondary income created by the production of electric power. They used multipliers which related increased output in electro-process industries to income induced in the local economy by that output. This was used in conjunction with estimates of output per kilo- watt for aluminum and other electro-process industries to estimate the induced income from the electrical output of the project. The derivation of the multipliers apparently 243 used an input-output type model. The multipliers were taken from a preliminary study done at the University of Washington. In addition to the regional definition problems in- volved in determining the relevant regional multipliers in this case, there are the problems of forecasting the users of the output within that region once the region is defined. Whether or not the multipliers which were accepted ade- quately represent the probable pattern of secondary in- come accrual cannot be answered without a great deal of research. Again, the multiplier transplant derived from other areas is a problem. Perhaps of potentially equal im- portance, however, is the fact that the multipliers were taken from a preliminary draft of a study which was re- leased for comment only. It is an ever-present danger of such transplantation that the adaptor does not fully know or appreciate the rule-of-thumb adjustments which went into a model, the range and conditions of applicability, and the sensitivity of the individual components to slight differences in industrial composition. In summary, the CEMH Test Team generally held an appreciation for the aggregate supply aspects involved in income multiplication from the national viewpoint. However, they did not apply the same considerations to the analysis of regional secondary benefits. Very restrictive and often untenable assumptions were necessary to rationalize this differentiation between the two accounts. The team 244 apparently believed that resource mobility at the national level was at least partially restricted for time periods conforming to the impact period of the project. They be- lieved that because of the interation between project ex- penditures, project funding, and distributional effects of project outputs, the net secondary effects at the national level were unknowable. In estimating the regional multi- plier effects, the team used transplanted multipliers quite liberally. In one case, the degree of refinement of the transplant multiplier was not yet acceptable to its devel- oper. Additionally, several of the multipliers used dealt with gross income generated rather than net income. In all, despite the quickness herein to point out their fail- ures, the team did a commendable job on many counts. They were at times even insightful, especially in dealing with the alternative costs of the labor and capital in the national account and in pointing out the often overlooked aspects of industrial diversification and employment stability. University of Wisconsin Test Team The University of Wisconsin (UWMH) Test Team report22 dealt largely with the development of a planning-decision model for choosing among public water resource investments. An integral part of that model had to do with the secondary income effects of the project. Though these effects were not treated as extensively as in some other test team 245 reports, some aspects of the treatment presented by the UWMH Test Team constituted significant contributions in dealing with the evaluation of secondary impacts. Perhaps the most important contribution of the UWMH Test Team in regard to secondary benefits was their ap- proach to inter-regional income effects of the project. Their desire to incorporate this effect into an explicit decision model led them to attempt to conceptualize an operational approach to the measurement of the project im- pacts both in the project region and in other regions of the country. In doing so, they divided the country into three regions: 1) The project region - i.e. the state of Idaho, 2) the contiguous region, defined as the states of Washington and Oregon, and 3) the rest of the nation. They then attempted to evaluate the primary project impacts upon the three regions of the country. The principal primary effect evaluated was that caused by the increased availability of irrigation water. It was assumed in the analysis that adjustments would be made by project area farmers which would increase the average size of farms (and thus the efficiency of the operation). This process would at the same time open up new farming opportunities in the project area, which would attract new farmers to the area. The result would be an increase in input purchases in the area, an increase in 246 agricultural income, and an increase in raw materials for agricultural processing and marketing firms. All of these would have secondary effects upon other producers in the project area. At the same time, however, as the UWMH Test Team pointed out, the new farmers necessary to take advantage of the new farming Opportunities provided by the project must come from somewhere. To illustrate their suggested approach, the team arbitrarily assumed that half of the new project farmers would come from the contiguous region and that the other half would come from the rest of the nation. In their discussion, they emphasized that the provision of the new farmers was not costless to the economy and that the effects upon the economy of the region from which they would come should also be evaluated. The effects envi- sioned would be of the same nature as those evaluated for the project region, except the effects realized by the other regions would be negative. Thus, declines outside of the region in farm income, agricultural supply sales and agri- cultural processing opportunities should be evaluated for the other regions just as they were being evaluated for the project region. The UWMH Test Team also pointed out that those people who would be attracted to project farm land from within the region should not be considered as costless resources either. The team felt that deductions from new farm in- come should be made to reflect the income given up in 247 other employment by these new farmers. In the case of both these farmers and those attracted from outside of the region, the principle was presented that the alternative cost of the new income should be considered in appraising the net changes in income. While the UWMH Test Team Report made some very valua- ble contributions on other accounts, their most important contribution to secondary benefit evaluation lay in their insistence upon the inclusion of the opportunity cost of the expansion effects. They discussed these opportunity costs in two contexts: l) The regional economic costs in the form of income foregone in other regions, and 2) the personal economic costs in the form of the income foregone in other employment (in some cases in another region). In evaluating the expansion effects of the project, the UWMH Test Team traced through only the first round of eexpenditures using a very aggregated industrial classifica- tzion scheme (the team's approach was similar in many ways ‘CID the Rent Model). The degree of aggregation accepted was £5€3emingly an item of convenience, since - as the team .F’C>inted out - they were interested only in demonstrating ti}1