o -.. _ -u‘.. ' o - . .--.. - ._, o a... - a» u I Q . . - u. . ‘ '>. .~ 5 . -.. - ..._'-.‘ _ > ‘ a.....,l..“ .' . .- u. ‘ .... Q- o y . . I -...' .w. . .. . ‘ .‘g§_. .. - \7 , . . o . .."‘ . .l _ Q. - s ”.“> ‘. .-_. ._‘-' .. .. . .... c,‘ - 0“ ‘- ~_~ ‘."'. .. . H... ~ A - u ‘s w'.‘ . ..- \“\ -v' . .~‘-r v._ . . ~ “' .‘s. ‘ _ - . I -,.--J o In. . v u.‘ '.‘ c Q \o‘ t .1 '. ..- '. - -- Q‘.‘- ‘ - .. ls“ § ..4 '. " r. . ‘ A .Q .. 1' 'I D. . § an.‘ F. o ." .1 .. 7 §-- ‘ ‘0 ABSTRACT METROPOLITAN DOMINANCE AND THE PERSISTENCE OF THE URBAN-RURAL FERTILITY DIFFERENTIAL: A DISTRIBUTIVE APPROACH TO THE STUDY OF FACTORS AFFECTING URBAN- RURAL FERTILITY IN THE UNITED STATES, 1960 by Rodger R. Rice This dissertation focuses on factors associated with the urban—rural fertility differential in the United States. The parameters of the problem are presented in the form of requisites for current differential fertility research. Differential fertility analysis requires a causal framework. Fertility is social group behavior explanable within an ecological framework. Prediction of convergence of urban- rural fertility levels does not necessitate termination of research on this differential but does indicate need for alternative approaches. Independent of convergence there remains variation within urban and rural fertility which requires explanation. Either a different set of factors affect urban and rural fertility or the same factors exert a different effect on urban and rural fertility. The tradi- tional aggregative approach is rejected in favor of the dis- tributive. Multiple regression analysis applied to inter- community fertility variation permits a comparative analysis of residential differential fertility patterns. ‘ v" ,, .. ..ru --- ‘1‘ _-- ‘ a -. - o -.- ""' . . -1 V— . .91. *-‘< ’ "Q av Ooh--- u.-.- ‘--‘ . v .u._ . -- o....-.. - .. .. I .‘---_- “‘- Q- .- b "h .- u , .~-.IIv a “!i - .- "" u-»- . . . w. ‘ .. Q--.. -. '0... , -. -. -‘ '2...- -.,_ ‘ v~ '. -"-_- c-.. .. fl. . ‘- - .. .r .. u“ ‘i. . O . . R .. ‘-- ~fi . .- ‘- '0 u ‘ .--‘ V . s ‘ -\. in --~ ._'_ ‘.~; Q g ‘0 '-'.. .Q ‘Q ~ . fl'c‘ ‘ ~ 5 'v. s .. ‘Q l-- '\ .- . - . . .‘ '0 "a. .. vs_ ‘- O o - I ‘ . ‘s - . ~ ~.. ‘\ . s 5 § 7 - D‘ -‘ . . Q -. Q ‘» n'q .,_ . a- ,‘ § -‘ . Q . "t ..¢ . I H .. Iv I.§ I.- - ‘s . U " J ‘. t O - n '0. ‘Q - Q \ . , ._ « '- . s . . . 5 I‘- fl ' n . § . I Q, ‘_ ‘ . , " n-‘ ‘ q. , - ‘ ~ Rodger R. Rice A review of empirical studies provides evidence (1) tlurt no previous study had implemented these requisites but (2) that contrasting patterns of differential fertility annong residential categories are plausible. In view of this ‘A/ ‘l \v/ .. ~-" sand the conclusion that urban dominance theory logically lnypothesizes the blurring of urban-rural differences, urban dominance theory is rejected and metropolitan dominance theory accepted as the theoretical framework by which to explain contrasting patterns of differential fertility among residential categories and to generate hypotheses for testing. Seven hypotheses are derived from metropolitan dominance theory: 1. Community social structure is a function of metro— politan dominance; metropolitan dominance manifests a different impact on community social structure in urban and rural hinterlands. 2. Fertility is a function of community social structure and metropolitan dominance; community social struc- ture and metropolitan dominance manifest a different impact on fertility in urban and rural hinterlands. 3. Urban and rural hinterland fertility is not only a function of metropolitan dominance, but also of con— ditions of its immediate locality. 4. Fertility is more a function of metropolitan domi— nance in the urban hinterland, but more a function of local community social structure in the rural hinterland. 5. Metropolitan dominance is more important in account— ing for variation in community social structure and fertility in both urban and rural hinterlands in the more metropolitan geographic divisions compared with the less metropolitan geographic divisions. 6. In the more metropolitan geographic divisions metro- politan dominance is more important in accounting for variation in urban and rural hinterland fertility u‘u :— .~ Rodger R. Rice than local community social structure; in less metro- politan geographic divisions local community social structure is more important in accounting for varia— tion in fertility than metropolitan dominance. 7. The impact of community social structure and metro- politan dominance on fertility manifest fewer dif— ferences when comparing the same type of hinterland communities (urban or rural) on an interdivisional basis than when comparing different types of hinter- land communities (urban vs. rural) on an intradivi- sional basis. Basic unit of analysis is the residential component of a county. Fertility, the dependent variable, is opera— tionalized as the cumulative fertility ratio. Operational- izing metropolitan dominance required deriving for all counties in the nation a numerical value reflecting distance from and size of a dominating metropolitan center. Community social structure is represented by eight empirical variables: employment of farmers and farm managers, farm laborers and foremen, education, family income, female income, female employment, ever—married females age 15—44 who were age 15-24 and 25-34. Analysis was limited to the white popula— tion of conterminous United States. A multiple regression analysis was performed for each of the residential catego- ries at the national and nine divisional levels. Analysis of statistical results provided confirmation of all hypotheses but the fourth. Confirmation of six of the hypotheses suggests the value of metropolitan dominance the- ory as a framework by which to explain the differential impact of factors in urban and rural hinterlands. METROPOLITAN DOMINANCE AND THE PERSISTENCE OF THE URBAN-RURAL FERTILITY DIFFERENTIAL: A DISTRIBUTIVE APPROACH TO THE STUDY OF FACTORS AFFECTING URBAN- RURAL FERTILITY IN THE UNITED STATES, 1960 BY Rodger R: Rice A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Sociology 1967 ! ’ c9319? _:-ao«é€ PREFACE Amateurs should be cautioned not to rush headlong into re- gression studies involving many variables. Some peOple think there is magic in the collection of vast amounts of data--that by some alchemy multiple regression will yield authentic information from careless measurements on heterogeneous material. The fact is that hazards increase with the extent and complexity of the in- vestigation.... However, do not be deterred if you have well taken measurements on carefully chosen material, and if you have definite questions whose answers lie in the methods to be used. As compared to the labor of getting the data the calculation of regression statistics is easy. George W. Snedecor, Statistical Methods (Ames: Iowa State Univer- sity Press, 1956), p. 434. ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS "Giving birth“ is a universal human experience. IDemographers treat it objectively, mothers live it subjec- tively. But "giving birth" is not the experience of mothers alone; it has happened to me. What mother could have ever survived a conception—parturition period of over five years? It happened to me. Intercourse, conception, "morning sick- ness," "depression," "labor pains," etc., they happened to lne. I am not knocking mothers, believe me, for without them this study would not have been possible. Retrospection at this point, however, tells me that "giving birth" is an ex- perience that takes on numerous forms in addition to child- ‘birth. Producing a dissertation is one of these forms. Yes, this is my baby, but many have contributed to its birth. Without them, an inevitable miscarriage. I wish to give special acknowledgment to Dr. J. Allan Beegle who served both as impregnator and obstetrician. An amazing feat? An amazing person, as many of my fellow graduate students (maternity mates?) do resound. I am appreciative of his fertile mind, his patience, his gentleness, and his ‘untiring interest in my case. Indeed, he is a good father and a good doctor all rolled into one. His professional staff is to be recognized and appreciated as well. I wish to thank the good doctors, J} W. Artis, Harvey Choldin, and'Walter E. Freeman of the .Department of Sociology and Charles Press, Chairman of the Department of Political Science, for their fruitful comments and maternal care. Without their professional concern, an inevitable stillbirth. Finally, to my life-long midwife and handholder, Ruth, and to her cherubic attendants, Sheri and Mark, how can I repay you for your unrelinquished vigilance and per— petual anticipation? As birth ends with the renewing of family ties, I ask only that you become my family once again. (And thank you too, Babar, for your companionship. Our family circle will be smaller without you.) iii fig. —-_... a- - o «- o .— Q . — -c u ‘v- 9 on \ PREFACE TABLE OF CONTENTS .ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF LIST OF Chapter I. II. TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . INTRODUCTION TO THE PROBLEM . . . . . . . . . Fertility as a Social Phenomenon . . . . . Fertility as an Important Demographic Variable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Differential Fertility . . . . . . . . . . The Goldberg Hypothesis . . . . . . . . . . The Causal Approach to Differential Fertility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Basic Design of the Study: Distributive Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary: Requisites of Needed Research on the Urban-Rural Fertility Differential . Origin and Organization of the Study . . . REVIEW OF RELEVANT LITERATURE . . . . . . . . Criteria Employed to Select Empirical Studies for Intensive Review . . . . . . Intensive Review of Selected List of Empirical Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . General Characteristics of Studies . . Study Design of Empirical Studies . . . Summary of Findings, by Variable . . . Resumé of Empirical Propositions from Intensive Review of Empirical Studies . . Distance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Agricultural Occupation . . . . . . . . Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Female Employment . . . . . . . . . . . Age Composition . . . . . . . . . . . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iv Page ii iii vi xvi 10 12 46 56 6O 74 76 79 82 89 96 98 101 136 137 138 139 140 141 141 142 Chapter III. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FOR STUDY OF DIFFERENTIAL FERTILITY . . . . . . . . Status of Differential Fertility Theory Critical Guidelines for a Theoretical Design for the Study of Differential Fertility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Theoretical Framework . . . . . . . . . Urban Dominance Theory . . . . . . Metropolitan Dominance Theory . . . Summary: Hypotheses Derived from Metropolitan Dominance Theory . . . . IV. METHODOLOGICAL PROCEDURES . . . . . . . . Conceptual Framework: Specification of Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Community Social Structure . . . . Metropolitan Dominance . . . . . . Community Fertility Behavior . . . Levels of Comparison . . . . . . . Statistical Framework: Specification of Statistical Techniques . . . . . . . Multiple Regression Model . . . . . Beta Coefficients . . . . . . . . . Coefficient of Multiple Determination Zero-Order Correlation Coefficients Partial Correlation Coefficients . Multiple-Partial Correlation Coefficients . . . . . . . . . . Statistical Tests . . . . . . . . . V. ANALYSIS OF DATA: NATION AND DIVISION . Hypothesis 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . Hypothesis 2 Hypothesis 3 Hypothesis 4 Hypothesis 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . Hypothesis 6 Hypothesis 7 Summary of Findings . . . . . . . . . . VI. REFLECTIONS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . BIBLIOGRAPHY . O O O O O O O O O O O C O O O O C Page 147 148 150 165 174 191 224 227 227 228 231 237 241 245 246 248 250 251 253 254 256 262 262 272 289 298 322 332 335 345 354 360 ~44 0‘.-- . I. .. .- . .... . ,, .. .. o‘- . . D - Table LIST OF TABLES Number and percentage change of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by nation and divisions, urban and rural: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . . . Percentage change of number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by nation and divisions, urban: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . . . . . . . Percentage change of number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by nation and divisions, rural: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . . . . . . . Percentage of total population urban for conterminous United States and divisions: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . . . . . . . Absolute differences in urban-rural number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by nation and divi— sions: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . . . Urban as a proportion of rural number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by nation and divisions: 1800 to 1840 and 1910 to 1960 . Rank order correlations of percentage of total population urban with absolute differences in urban-rural fertility ratios and urban to rural fertility ratios, for conterminous United States and divisions: 1800-1840 and 1910-1960 Number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white women by residence and age for conterminous United States and divisions, 1960 C O O O O O O O O O C O O O O O C O O 0 vi Page 19 23 23 24 29 29 33 37 'Iable 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. Percentage distribution of urban, rural-non- farm and rural-farm parts of counties by children ever born per 1,000 ever-married white women age 15—44 for conterminous United States and divisions: 1960 . . . . . . . . . Urban-rural components of decline in number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by divisions: 1810— 1940 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Urban—rural movement between 1935 and 1940 of native white women 15 to 49 years old, by marital status and number of own children under 5 years old in 1940 . . . . . . . . . . Distribution of the white civilian population 18 years of age and over, by residence, farm or nonfarm birthplace, United States, 1958 . . Summary table of fertility studies selected for intensive review . . . . . . . . . . . . . Summary table of relationships of fertility to independent variables based on fertility studies selected for intensive review . . . . Tabular summary of empirical propositions by independent variable and residence category: expected relationships of fertility to selected independent variables and expected relative importance of independent variables in determining fertility variation within residence groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Distribution of population in the United States and divisions, by metropolitan status 1960 O O C O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Zero-order correlation of metropolitan domi- nance and employment in agricultural occupa— tions (urbanization) for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . Zero—order correlation of metropolitan domi- nance and socio-economic status for contermi- nous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 vii Page 44 50 52 54 90 102 143 220 264 266 Table 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. Page Zero-order correlation of metropolitan domi— nance and wife's alternative opportunities for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 268 Zero-order correlation of metropolitan domi— nance and demographic age structure for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 270 Zero-order correlation of fertility and metro- politan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . 273 Zero-order correlation of fertility and employ— ment in agricultural occupations (urbanization) for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 275 Zero-order correlation of fertility and socio- economic status for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . 278 Zero-order correlation of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 281 Zero-order correlation of fertility and demo— graphic age structure for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . 283 Coefficients of multiple determination (R2) of fertility and variables in multiple regres- sion equations for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . 287 Comparison 3f coefficient of multiple deter- mination (R ) and multiple— partial correlation coefficient (r2 ) of fertility and community social structure controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . 292 Comparison of coefficient of multiple deter- mination (R2) and multiple— partial correlation coefficient (r2 ) of fertility and employment in agricultural occupations (urbanization) controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 293 viii . v-4.-. . - - o ‘ o . u. ‘0». :- O~ \ .' .‘os n 'Qr §-. - o.-- ‘0.... - .‘-‘ ‘Q- ‘ D— a... . ...~ .—I. . q»... - § ‘ h't- b . -_.‘ ... '\ '2'. § , s... ‘v. ~ -...‘ fl- - n -‘c‘ h. u_.: -._ -‘I g.‘ g §" §.. a.- 'l 'A.‘ ‘ 'Q _ . h- a . i v.‘ ‘F I :- C . §‘. §.. A . h.. 5-. ”V Q ."‘ I... -.~ I" . ‘. s - ‘fl. ~ . A b.‘ 5-. ‘§ - n 0'. D- u ‘§ § . ‘0- 's n A‘- ..i “‘ § O. .- ~ - —- a- 5- a. o. ~. ‘. h- u -v- u ‘ u. ‘.I' -- §. " .o .- ‘6 \ ~~ o- .._ 'u “s a s '. d~ ~._ ’.' ‘. ‘ ”A 5 s a" '- '— ... - "s ‘ 5 . -._ 'u ‘. a 7 ‘Q. A g c a,‘ '- a y ‘. - s § 4.. ‘0 ‘. c Table 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. Comparison of coefficient of multiple deter- mination (R2) and multiple—partial correlation coefficient (r2) of fertility and socio—economic status controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Comparison of coefficient of multiple deter— mination (R2) and multiple-partial correlation coefficient (r2) of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . Comparison of coefficient of multiple deter- mination (R2) and multiple—partial correlation coefficient (r2) of fertility and demographic age structure controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relativg importance in accounting for variation in fertility for New England division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relativg importance in accounting for variation in fertility for Middle Atlantic division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . Beta coefficient (B') and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for East North Central division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for West North Central division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relativg importance in accounting for variation in fertility for South Atlantic division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . ix Page 294 295 296 306 308 309 311 312 Table Page 37. Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for East South Central division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . 314 38. Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for West South Central division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . 315 39. Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for Mountain division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . 316 40. Beta coefficient (B-) and rank of independent variable by relative importance in accounting for variation in fertility for Pacific division, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . 318 41. Average rank among divisions of relative importance of independent variables in accounting for variation in fertility mea— sured by Beta coefficients, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 320 42. Zero-order correlation coefficients (r2) of metropolitan dominance and community social structure for divisions by level of metro— politanization, urban: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . 324 43. Zero-order correlation coefficients (r2) of metropolitan dominance and community social structure for divisions by level of metropol- itanization, rural-nonfarm: 1960 . . . . . . . 327 44. Zero-order correlation coefficients (r2) of metropolitan dominance and community social structure for divisions by level of metropol— itanization, rural—farm: 1960 . . . . . . . . . 328 45. Rank of metropolitan dominance by relative importance for variation in fertility based on Beta coefficients and zero-order correla— tion coefficient of metropolitan dominance and fertility for divisions by level of metropolitanization, by residence: 1960 . . . . 330 ... ._ ..u ~q ~.« ‘4‘ . . ._. . . . .v r. L. .o . . . . o . :. .. o. o . I. ... u .1. :. . . ..1 . . v. .4. n . . On . . .H — ... .. — ... _u .. .. a.“ o. .. .n. I. o‘. o. p“ .x. .. n. ... .3 . . ..u ..H n. .. o. Table Page 46. Average rank of independent variable by rela— tive importance in accounting for variation in fertility measured by Beta coefficients by level of metropolitanization of divisions and by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . 334 47. Summary of results for multiple comparison tests among residential sectors of contermi— nous United States divisions . . . . . . . . . . 338 48. Summary of results for multiple comparison tests between divisions of conterminous United States by residential sector . . . . . . 342 49. First-order partial correlation of fertility and employment in agricultural occupations (urbanization) controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . 372 50. First-order partial correlation of fertility and socio—economic status controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . 373 51. First-order partial correlation of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities control- ling for metropolitan dominance for contermi- nous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 374 52. First-order partial correlation of fertility and demographic age structure controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 . . . 375 53. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county--conterminous United States: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 376 .54“ Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children evern born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15—44, for rural- nonfarm part of county--conterminous United States: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 377 po- .. U . -~vv~.-‘. was.-- , “~V- V':V - .‘U. ‘Q . n. . Jr Q... g . - .‘¢~ .. u... ‘ o5u-‘i‘ —-- ‘v _ .- “1...... _ "Vv.. _ - b. ~‘..~_‘ . r... g. - ~"' .- . . Q "- .. -_.~ ‘ ..._.-_ . - V "*.L_. --,"‘ . ‘ I h“"§- -‘-.~'— . "~~.-‘_ ‘0 In -..- . - n 'l: L ..‘_-‘~ .-—. ' .._ K“ ~:".- . . .‘-‘~_ - ‘zv- , ‘ n. _ _ .... . . . 4:- ...‘ . - o ." "\ D- l ‘ ‘ _‘_\ ."~, .n‘-- ‘_'v.. “n.‘-, . _“s - h“ -. -~‘ . -‘ I. 4r .- ' c - "Q . n‘. “ ._h“ \ . ‘. p "u.--. ' 3 ~.-’ ' .. _' .‘.. ‘ ¢_ . - -.. a. ‘ ~ —.‘~ '1‘. ~‘ s -. ~§_ o ... s I ~ .5: 'y.‘ C “‘:. ‘- n. 'r n. . ‘§ “ -V‘ g ‘ “§ . ‘v - a ‘. _ .‘§ . b u‘ .v I a,“ “' v 0 . v-_ ‘ ‘-:. .. C s‘: 5 \ I, ._ -‘.. ‘- ‘ ~_ ~...'-’,. ‘Q .. ~- . O b‘-"‘ Qfi“ ’; ‘- v‘ r. ‘ ‘4’ .U Table Page 55. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural- farm part of county——conterminous United States: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 378 56. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county-—New England division: 1960 . . 379 57. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural- nonfarm part of county-—New England division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 380 58. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural- farm part of county--New England division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 381 59. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for urban part of county-~Middle Atlantic division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 382 60. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural— nonfarm part of county-—Middle Atlantic divi— sion: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 383 61. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for rural— farm part of county—-Middle Atlantic division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 384 62. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county-~East North Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 385 xii . O a in. ~ . or- Q. . - - '_: ' ‘~- . Q” I~~* —-, . r a- -v. 5“ . ‘- '4' .- .*~. . "- \ u- r ~. _- I ._ ‘N v 9‘ ”a '. -- t o - ! (I 'tl l(' (H ‘1 Table 63. 64. 65. 66. 67. 68. 69. 70. Page Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for rural- nonfarm part of county-~East North Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 386 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural-farm part of county-—East North Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 387 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county--West North Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 388 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15—44, for rural- nonfarm part of county--West North Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 389 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for rural- farm part of county--West North Central divi— sion: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 390 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for urban part of county—~South Atlantic division: 1960 . 391 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for rural— nonfarm part of county--South Atlantic divi— sion: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 392 Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural- farm part of county—-South Atlantic division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 393 xiii -u w. 1.. . w... ~A Table 71. 72. 73. 74. 75. 76. 77. 78. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county-—East South Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for rural- nonfarm part of county-—East South Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural— farm part of county--East South Central divi- sion: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county-—West South Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for rural- nonfarm part of county-—West South Central division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for rural- farm part of county--West South Central divi- sion: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county--Mountain division: 1960 . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever married white females, age 15-44, for rural- nonfarm part of county-—Mountain division: 1960: . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiv Page 394 395 396 397 398 399 400 401 c .‘v‘ .n-‘ ono. .,. a, ‘ Jr a.-. . ~ ‘0‘. .‘ 1-. ~ o u-..._ - -In' .- 0-“--. -«".~ ‘ ‘ a -‘...‘ . . 0.,.. -- ‘-.. V. o . I .-. .‘ ~_‘ ~ ’ “ o-._ .--...' “-5..-. --"‘. - D h-..-‘-- a D‘.."- "-0.-“ ., - dr Q-.. ‘ I ‘R ‘~ Q _‘ ‘ .u,‘.-‘ I. -. ‘V “is..- " h- ~ 4"... _-.‘-‘ . n .u -" .- -§ Table 79. 80. 81. 82. Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15—44, for rural— farm part of county—-Mountain division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15-44, for urban part of county—-Pacific division: 1960. . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever— married white females, age 15—44, for rural- nonfarm part of county—~Pacific division: 1960 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Results of the analysis of factors influencing number of children ever born per 1,000 ever- married white females, age 15—44, for rural— farm part of county--Pacific division: 1960 . XV Page 402 403 404 405 vm .._ \- v Appendix A. “A LIST OF APPENDICES Page DETAILED RESULTS OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION EQUATIONS (See Tables 49—82, List of Tables) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 371 CHECKLIST FOR SELECTING STUDIES FOR INTENSIVE REVIEW . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 406 xvi . m": -. - ‘ ' ..-__~_ - -_ .~ ‘ ‘ d.. - -..¢‘.m.~ ’ . ;-‘...- ‘-~ _ \.~ ~ -..- “‘ .-. -- . ‘. _. ‘ ..‘.-- - . « ..~:§.-.‘. ‘ - n. b‘ ‘.-.‘_-- c - .- ‘- \ ._~ - ‘- T Q ~.- ‘ ‘- ‘ ~- .. c.‘ ‘ . .. . .- .. - g‘ . - ~.. ‘ 7 ‘~ ‘~‘ ~‘v_‘. J1 ~ .~ ‘ -- .~ I _ . . - . . - “H . -‘~ ~ - ‘ ‘- ~d“‘ ‘. .‘ ‘ V .- -.‘ n. w. I o .1 -. I 'z- . ‘ . .-\. ‘_-. ‘d- ‘ a- \ - . ‘.‘ ‘0 . ..‘. ‘- . ~ g u‘ “3". _.‘ . - -_A . \~ ‘ s|. I . ‘ ~ u‘N - -' ._-‘ . ‘~ ~\ s‘ ‘ . - .‘ CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION TO PROBLEM Fertility as a Social Phenomenon Fertility is a common but complex phenomenon. It affects many aspects of a society, is affected by the same, and captures the interest of many levels of society. It affects and is reflected in industrial manpower, family structure, educational facilities, housing, ad nauseam. Fundamentally it is society's recruitment process. Its relevance is so extensive that no discipline can claim it in its entirety. Ryder has commented that "the fields of learning which have been most immediately con— cerned with and instrumental in the understanding of fertil- ity are sociology, biology, and, to a lesser extent, econom- ics, anthropology and psychology. No science concerned with man has ignored or could properly ignore the 'facts of life.'"1 In this study it will be argued that fertility is to a large extent a social phenomenon, i.e., though it is a 1N. B. Ryder, "Fertility," in Philip Hauser and Otis IMMfley Duncan, The Studyyof Population (Chicago: University ofcnucago Press, 1959), p. 400. .. ...-_- 0' . o .,. ‘fibbv- - — .— --- 0---. -- c- . ‘7’. ... ' O; o . . , . I a It 1' -- -. .-- .. . _ - ‘ - ., \ ..-.-_-__ ..,,_- -- .~.-‘ ~ . "9.. D '- - n. .'v- _ - ‘V‘.-- Y -. .~ . ' --_ ..y‘>v - - O - . -. ~v . . -. .-‘ _ t_‘ u. . u"- “ ‘O “_u - -V s ‘-, ‘Q- ._. .s -- -b ‘ l .,. h ‘ ’ _ .. ~- .~ F“ s --. ‘ a '- .‘- - “-.. -‘\-- “ _ . ---. ~.\. ‘ ‘i --‘C s o ‘ Q ‘ “.~ ~ .-- n‘ ‘ . a ‘ u ‘ ‘- . n. ‘. . . ‘Q Q s " ~ - ~ I "v _ » -§ 9 i u . .I. ‘ \“s. -‘, ‘ ‘~ biological fact, social factors play a significant role in the determination of the biological result. Considering the absence of modern contraceptive devices and controls, it is quite likely that biological factors are more important in determining fertility levels in primitive and underdevelOped societies. However, Lorimer2 and Davis and Blake3 have sug- gested the possibility that even in underdevelOped areas fertility levels are influenced significantly by social and cultural factors. Davis and Blake write: A striking feature of underdeveloped areas is that vir— tually all of them exhibit a much higher fertility than do urban-industrial societies. This well-documented but insufficiently analyzed fact is known to be connected with profound differences in social organization as between the two types of society, and is, therefore, significant for the comparative sociology of reproduc- tion. The clarity and importance of the contrast, how- ever, should not be allowed to obscure the equally important fact that underdeveloped areas themselves differ markedly in social organization, and that these differences appear to bring about variations in fertil- ity.q Previously with respect to urban-industrial societies there was a "respectable body of opinion to the effect that group differences in fertility reflected differences in biological 2Frank Lorimer, Culture and Human Fertility (New York: International Documents Service, Columbia University Press, 1955). 3Kingsley Davis and Judith Blake, "Social Structure amiFértility: {An Analytical Framework," Economic Develop- 33m; and Cultural Change, Vol. IV (1956), pp. 211-35 4Ibid., p. 211 (italics mine). capacity to reproduce,"5 a view advocated as recently as the 1920's and 30's by such leading demographers as Gini6 and Pearl.7 This Opinion has since subsided in the shadow of the sudden upsurge in fertility levels of urban populations. Beginning with the Indianapolis Study many efforts have been made to relate psychological factors to fertility differences, but seemingly with little success. Kiser and Whelpton's own evaluation of the Indianapolis Study's effort in this direction suggests the insignificance of such factors. The Indianapolis Study presents a challenge to learn the reasons for the overriding influence of socio-economic status. There is good reason to believe that it is not socio—economic status per se but rather the underlying attitudes and psychological characteristics of these classes that account for the fertility behavior. And yet, whereas characteristic patterns of fertility dif- ferentials are found consistently in classifications by socio-economic status, most classifications by psycho- logical characteristics within socio—economic groups fail to show such patterns.BI h1a.critica1 review of the Indianapolis Study, Hauser and Duncan assail the authors for not appearing "to entertain 5Clyde V. Kiser, "Differential Fertility in the United States," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and Economic Change in Develgped Countries (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960), p. 77. _ 6C. Gini, "The Cyclical Rise and Fall of Population," JJIPOpulation, Harris Foundation Lectures (Chicago: Univer- sity of Chicago Press, 1929). 7Raymond Pearl, The Biology of Population Growth (NEW York: Knopf, 1925). . 8C. V. Kiser and P. K. Whelpton, "Resume of the Inxhanapolis Study of Social and Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility," Population Studies, Vol. VII (1953), P- 08. .. a . ‘ v ...- 2.0-"- I'- ' r“ 'N' . ' o h . ‘ ~ 5 ..u .0. ' Or' ‘ r '. a... . .. - ~ ‘.1 .U-D' ' -0” -' t.y-:- ~|-'. ~- . ba- ‘-.' 4.1 o A. ". ...... _ .. . u -d. .. -__ v- . ' . ""- ~q-— . s u ""-'v w-..u— ' a "‘ ’- a- -......_ v K ' I . n. .' ‘.-.~ ~ . n. s..gg '._ r ‘ ....‘.-.‘- . o U. _ . - , a -" u. -: .-‘ ‘. “ J b 'n n- -. _ h _ ‘ 9" .. _~ .' v .0 . -- .‘. ._'. . ‘ ‘ "o .-‘. . -‘. v. . - ‘°“.¢.,_“ .._ ‘ . ‘..‘-c -. - v- ‘."I . h I..-...‘-' H.- . ..' - .‘h’ 5‘: “ s ,. sue-” ‘ . -_ -- “n -- u '0 ‘ I. " ' h v , 0 I. . '0 . .. -‘-‘_ ‘I - ‘ ‘J "‘c ‘:.~ .. a 4 ‘ 'C t. .. V ‘Q‘- . a. u _ g .i “- o “. v a | "-§n smriously the supposition that psycho-social variables actu- ally are not very important or useful as eXplanatory factors. nlfact, their own comments on their results provide a re- markable example of maintaining a hypothesis tenaciously in the face of rather consistently negative evidence."9 Studies conducted since the Indianapolis Study have contin- Lmd to discover consistently low correlations between psy- chological variables and fertility, even when fertility is Immsured as "desired size of family," a measure which would smem to be at a level more relevant to a psychological analysis.lo Another important consideration is the extent to “mich intentional family limitation practices explain dif— ferences in fertility levels of various subgroups of modern Society. .A United Nations publication in an extensive review of the economic and social factors affecting fertility 9P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Population (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959), p. 99. 10See as examples of such studies: R. Gutman and I. Bender, "Some Sources of Variation in Family Size of College f this differential. The best known and most soundly docu— nnented generalization for the United States with respect to Ciifferential fertility is the long-term continual decline of tihe magnitude of the urban-rural fertility differential.25 (Stabill, Kiser and Whelpton note that, while the urban-rural (iifferential in fertility is among the oldest and best known <>f demographic phenomena, it has narrowed considerably in tihe United States. In commenting on the outlook for fertil— Iity differentials they state: It seems likely . . . that the long—range trend will be toward continued narrowing of group differences in fer- tility. The differences between rural and urban areas with respect to style of life are being lessened by 25A few examples of this documentation are W. H. (Srabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, The Fertility of {Emerican WOmen, op. cit.; W. H. Grabill, "The Fertility of ‘the United States Population," in Donald J. Bogue, Egg liopulation of the United States (Glencoe: The Free Press, .1959), pp. 288-324; C. V. Kiser, "Differential Fertility in 'the United States," op. cit.; C. V. Kiser, "Changes in Fer- ‘tility by Socio-Economic Status during 1940-50," Milbank bdemorial Fund Quarterly, XXXIII (October, 1955), 393-429; C!.Eh Westoff, "Differential Fertility in the United States: .1900 to 1952," American Sociological Review, XIX (October, 1954), 549-61; and Bernard Okun, Trends in Birth Rates in ;the United States Since 1870 (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1958) . '.A Q .u-I-u- u... .— .' ~- . . .... ,. n 0.! h II“ ".an _. ~Q--.... o... c- . "..-A‘ ‘ .. ."~~ ' §.—. .-.d ‘ ... I - a . u ': Q ‘ § .- , ‘— ‘. ~ .. P .- ‘u n v. .- “0 ‘. ~‘c s u ' _ s \ '.‘ - ~ . u_~ ‘ ‘ n ‘\ - 5y . " .' . ¥I ‘:' a I l . .l. . _. 14 reduction in the relative size of the farm population, by improvements in highways and means or transportation, and by television, radio, and movies. . . . Selective factors alone probably will continue to account for appreciable urban-rural differences in fertility, but, in general, the outlook is for reduction in the magni— tude of these differentials.26 Several plausible explanations have been proposed :ftm the contraction of the traditional urban-rural fertility (iifferential: (l) the spread of contraceptive practice tzhrough all strata of the population, thus, virtually elim- jgnating the differential use of contraception as a basis for (Sifferential fertility; (2) the high degree of consensus of E: large majority of Americans in an ideal family size rang— :ing from two to four;27 and (3) the blurring of class dif— :ferences in the United States as the working class takes (on many middle class characteristics and the function of 26W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. Whelpton, The liertilipy of American Women, op. cit., p. 378. 27Judith Blake, "Ideal Family Size Among White Amer- :icans: A Quarter of a Century of Evidence," Demography, III, ISO. 1 (1966), 154—73 (Blake says, "the two-to—four child Itange has encompassed the ideals of approximately 80 to 90 19ercent of men and women since the middle of the 1930's"). ESee also David Goldberg, "Fertility and Fertility Differen— ‘tials: Some Observations on Recent Changes in the United EStates" in M. C. Sheps and J. C. Ridley, Public Health and IPopulation Changp_(Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh ZPress, 1965), pp. 131-32; Ronald Freedman, David Goldberg, and Doris Slesinger, "Current Fertility Expectations of Idarried Couples in the United States," Population Index, JXXIX (October, 1963), 366-91; and R. Freedman, D. Goldberg, and.D. Slesinger, "Fertility EXpectations in the United EStates: 1963," Population Index, XXX (April, 1964), 171-75. .0...— ‘ ‘- \ . u -x ‘\ ~ ~ o u. . c .‘ 1 § ' - \' \ ~ .\ y 1 n \ 15 (rhildren and the family become more similar in the different ssocial strata of the population.28 With respect to urban—rural differences in general rnany sociologists and demographers have forecast the even— trual demise of most urban—rural differences on the basis of xvhich one can infer the eventual eclipse of the fertility ciifferential. For example, Robin Williams asserts: Were it possible to make a systematic comparison of all major aspects of American social life in 1900 and in the 1960's, we would probably find a consistent decrease in the sharpness of differentiation between and among major social statuses, categories and collectivities. Rural- urban differences clearly are less. Class differentials are less obvious or sharp. Occupational status differ— ences are blurred, eSpecially between manual and non— manual jobs. . . . Regional distinctiveness, in spite of temporary resurgence in situations of conflict, gradually diminishes. Ieran-rural disparities will disappear as our society lbecomes more dominantly urban as Comhaire and Cahnman com- Inent: The industrial society in which we live is urban through and through, especially in the United States, where the farmer is a business man who keeps a sharp eye on domes— tic and world markets, applies scientific methods in 28Kurt Mayer, "Fertility Changes and Population I?orecasts in the United States,” Social Research, XXVI, ISO. 3 (Autumn, 1959), 347-66. 29RObin M. Williams, Jr., "American Society in Tran- Sition: Trends and Emerging Development in Social and Cul- 'tura1 Systems," in James H. Copp, Our Changing Rural Sociepy: lierspectives and Trends (Ames: Iowa State University Press, 51964), pp. 23-24. See also Norman Ryder, "Variability and (Zonvergence in the American Population," Phi Delta Kappan, XLI (June, 1960), 379-383. 16 seeding and feeding, owns a car and a television set, and has his wife and daughter dressed according to the latest fashion. . . . Ecologically speaking, the Amer- ican farmer does not live in the city, yet his ways are citified. He is g; the city even though he is not lp' the city.30 The question might be stirring in the reader's mind eat this point whether it is even profitable to investigate iiurther the urban—rural differential in fertility, whether i:t is profitable to proceed with this very study, given the irnevitable convergence of urban—rural fertility levels? The Etnswer must be affirmative, though certainly new approaches 21nd techniques of analysis must be investigated and tried. (Ioldberg justifies the continuation of research in this area Vihen he states: With the exception of certain types of historical data, American fertility patterns are probably better docu- mentated than in any other country. To document a pattern, however, does not explain it. On the whole, our understanding_of fertility_differentials is negli— gible. Moreover, what we thought we knew in the past, the relationships we took for granted, are being seri— ously questioned by some recent research. In fact, the most exciting research on differentials during the past few years has either negated what was thought to be true in the past or has found differentials to be increasing precisely in those areas for which contraction had been predicted.31 3OJean Comhaire and Werner J.Cahnman, How Cities (grey-r (Madison, New Jersey: The Floram Park Press, 1959) , 31David Goldberg, "Fertility and Fertility Differen— ‘tials: Some Observations on Recent Changes in the United EStates," op. cit., p. 120. ..... » I .u- -.-o . . ..- con - o- ..D- ..< o .w r. ‘ ., . .~- .-. ~‘ C.- "‘ 0,. a. _ - . ..__ i . ‘.- _ 'G.. h._ ‘ . ‘- ._ _‘ '-. . ~ .; .~ ‘- -. ~ - ‘\ ‘ ~ -5 - ‘- s s ‘. . {.7 ‘ . C‘. u \ ¢ . '.‘ .t ‘ ‘u '. .‘_ ‘ ‘\ . . \ ~u I! ."~ \ 5“. ‘ § . \ . §‘ .. . ‘_ c . .. . '. _ § \ " s “ . 1 0 ~ . 17 Fertility is a complex phenomenon. Convergence of fertility levels does not ring the death knell of differen- tial fertility analysis, but understandably indicates that 11ew relationships are perhaps develOping. As fertility Ipatterns change, our approach to analysis must also change. (31d techniques are not adequate or sensitive enough to per- mrit the intensive scrutiny necessary to sufficiently under— srtand and eXplain complex fertility behavior. With near exxhaustive documentation of fertility differentials past and crurrent, we have discovered much in terms of fertility pat- tuerns, but more questions than answers have emerged. At- t:empts to eXplain fertility behavior must continue; new qnaestions must be formulated; different approaches and tech- Iliques must be eXplored. Besides, urban-rural fertility <3ifferences still have not completely disappeared,32 though tlue'magnitude of the fertility differential is diminishing. Answering such questions as what factors are associated with lxrban fertility, what factors are associated with rural fer- tlility, and are these sets of factors dissimilar, may help ‘10»better understand current urban and rural fertility :Levels and to judge more accurately the future status of the ‘eran—rural fertility differential. To set the backdrop for 32See Leo F. Schnore, "The Rural-Urban Variable: An Ieranite's PerSpective," Rural Sociology, XXXI, No. 2 (June, 1966), 131-43; and J. Allan Beegle, "Social Structure and (Ihanging Fertility of the Farm Population," Rural Sociology, XXXI, No. 4 (December, 1966), 415—27. 18 this attempt to investigate the why of residential fertility variation, let us ponder past and current trends of the urban-rural fertility differential within the United States. Table 1 presents the trends in urban and rural fer— tility ratios, measured as the number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, for the period 1800 to 1960, for only the white population of the United States and its geographic divisions. The table indi— cates quite clearly that, although rural fertility ratios have persistently maintained a higher level than urban ratios, for the nation and all divisions the fertility ratios of the rural population have kept pace with those of the urban population in a pattern of gradual diminution. In fact, when measured in absolute decline, the rural popula— tion reveals the greater declines in fertility levels. On a national basis both the urban and rural ratios of children under 5 years old dropped between 1810 and 1840 by about 200 clhildren per 1,000 women (rural 195; urban 199) . Between 1840 and 1910, however, the decline amounted to 352 in the rural population and only 232 for the urban. Again between 1910 and 1940 the urban ratio fell by 158 children per 1,000 Women, the rural ratio by 231. The divisions for these same Periods reflect a similar pattern of greater absolute reduc— tion of rural fertility ratios, although for the period 1910-1940 the more urban divisions (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North Central) reverse this pattern. ab. 0" . u n 0 - ~§ - . s u a - v I .5. - s o Q .50. Q Q . . Q - -c I n 0.! u.- - uua ‘ul.u I I 1 , .. I .0: \l a... I.|o .- u 1 o I . - t . I‘Quo- I I on 0...! > D O I c 0 II: I O: on I I I .n. I. at. . ". uh I .v‘ .I. .0...) .0 I at u v I 0.. 1" ll 0.00.... In: - n O... L .D‘v on. .- \ .-.~I , I.....,. D a... u. (lu.ean‘ 1.9 .mmlnm .dd .Amoma .umnEouoo .ommUALO mo muwmuw>asa .xmoHowoom wo ucoeuummoo .COMumuuommac .o.£m pmzmaandmsdv :mmumum pouwcb msu ca moocouwwuan xuaaauumm cons: aw mucuomm can become: .wazmmm .w cmuasm ”mousom .cowuwcwmmp swan: GAO so Ummmmc ... ... ... ... ... ... ... m.oml m.oau N.MHI ... ... ... m.mml m.oHI m.vml ¢.mml o.mml o.hHI o.val ovma looma ... ... ... ... v.o¢I o.vml v.mvl m.mm| 0.5m: o.vml m.mml h.m¢I H.¢v| o.nvl ¢.0ml v.mm| o.oml ~.m~l a.mml o.Hm1 onH Iovma ¢.H~| N.h~l m.mal 0.0m: A.Nm1 m.mml o.mml h.¢~l H.hm1 m.mm| m.mml ~.mml 0.0m: h.oml ~.~v| h.mml ¢.Hml n.HNI h.~mu m.mml oema loama h.m~H ~.~o h.mm o.mm m.mm m.v~ m.~m H.m H.mo m.va n.mHH h.Hm h.ooa m.ov h.ooa m.hm H.mm «.05 m.¢oa o.mm wWMM chmcu mmmucwuuom ... ... ... ... ... ... ... moh.H How mom.H ... ... ... o¢m.H «mm omm.a hum oNH.H m¢m mam.d coma ... ... ... ... hmh 5mm.H mem.a Hon.H 0mm h¢m.~ ... oam.~ om~.H mon.H emm ¢¢M.H mew mno.~ com mmm.H oama ... ... ... ... mom -m.u mmo.a mmm.a Hmm oam.a ... mmo.H mmo.a 0H0.H New mm~.H won Nmm Hmm wh~.H omwa ... ... ... ... hum mo¢.H mom mmm.H hob mo~.a HmH.H moh.H cam ¢m¢.H NNh ooa.d VHO Hmm won omH.H OMmH ... ... ... ... mew mmv.H amm ¢Nv.H ohh mmH.H mow Hmv.H H¢m Hm~.H Han woo.H «on com Hon VMH.H o¢ma com ovw 00¢ on com hum owe mum mow vow one 005 one who mmfi omo mo¢ mom mwv th Gama wen moo Orv how mwc mwm Ace pew mme Hmm ode dab mme moo How omo oom Noe ADV «eh owma won hon awe NAB oav mmh ¢H¢ awn Hov wen mom vao 00¢ moo wmm omm ha¢ va mmm mmo OMmH mmm 90¢ woe new men Hmm mmm mew mom mom fimm mmm own mmm omN hmc HNM mev Han Hmm owed mnv «no one fimb ~¢m mom emv own One who ¢Hm Now How mum Nme 0mm owe «do mhv Mho comma mom new mom hob avm «on Now ems mew Now omm mon Hon «mo avv moo ¢m¢ mNo omv mmo omma mmo amp Neh mmm omo wmn wow wow mmm Ame moo 0H0 new mmn ehm omb wmw mmh wmo hes Gama Gonna Hausa Gonna Hausa Gonna Hausa :mnuD Hound Gonna Amusm cons: Hausa Gonna amusm Gonna amusm :mnHD Hausa can“: Hausa hum» Dauaomm :«mu::0: Huuucoo Hmuunoo oaucmHu< Hmuucoo amuucmo Uwucwuut pamamcm moumum susom amok nusom unmm nuaom nuuoz yum: nuuoz ummm mdccwz 3oz nouwab coma 0» oaoa can ovma 0» coma «Amunu can swan: .m:0anw>av cam ceauu: an .UHO numma vv 0» om soap: wads: coo.a hoe 0H0 numah m Moos: couoaaso no mucosa oomusoouom can uunisz .H canes 20 In terms of percentage change, however, the urban population reflects a greater rate of decline since 1800. Table 1 indicates for the periods 1800-1840, 1840—1910, and 1910-1940 rates of decline nationally for the rural popula— tion of 14.0 percent, 31.0 percent, and 29.5 percent respec- tively and for the urban population 17.0 percent, 33.1 per- cent and 32.7 percent respectively. For the nation and its divisions, generally the period from 1800 to 1940 is one of long term decline for both rural and urban fertility, although Tables 2 and 3 reveal exceptions to this pattern in various divisions for specific decades. More will be said concerning these later, but here it is worth contrast- ing the percentage change in urban and rural fertility ratios in the geographic divisions for the two broad periods of 1840-1910 and 1910—1940 (see Table l) . For the former Eperiod, fertility of pggal populations declined at faster rates'than urban in the more urbanized divisions (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North Central, West North Central). The more rural divisions indicate an opposite trend. Between 1910 and 1940 in the more urbanized divisions, the gr_bap_ fertility ratios dropped at a faster rate than the rural (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North Central, South Atlantic). The other divisions, becoming increasingly urban, resemble the pattern of the more urbanized divisions 0f the previous period, 1840-1910. This indicates an appar- ent lag on the part of the more rural divisions, but a rough ......ao-aw \‘ ‘ . .- £.'L.-o.vo~ -'. " I v ,_ _ _..Q .- 1“. ‘-:. - ‘ ~ ' .-' “u‘ -.o- s . .... ..- QAVOV‘ ‘ ...- ...-l ~g..‘-~‘\. - .u - -v. -.--y ~ A. . . a _‘ .' -budb ‘. o - - - -..-, -... .- ‘1 '* ~cv. a f" l" (I) i 21 Eissociation of urbanization and fertility decline obtains. (These data suggest a pattern of cycles in terms of the eXpan— ssion and contraction of urban—rural fertility levels. In eaarly stages of urbanization rural fertility ratios decline faster than urban ratios, contracting the differential. As Ilrbanization progresses, urban fertility ratios reduce :faster than rural ratios, eXpanding the differential. The foeriod 1940-60, a period of increasing fertility ratios for 130th urban and rural populations, indicates a contraction, tout by urban fertility levels increasing faster than rural Ilevels. Table 1 shows that in the more urbanized divisions (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North Central, West liorth Central, South Atlantic, Pacific) and for the nation 635 a whole, urban fertility levels increased at an extremely :fast pace, closing the gap between urban-rural fertility. i?able 6, which measures urban fertility ratios as a propor— tlion of rural fertility ratios, reflects this pattern of GEXpanding-contracting cycles for all divisions. As a result <>f the "baby boom" era of 1940-60, urban-rural fertility (iifferentials for all divisions and the nation are closer ‘to unity than ever before in their history. This pattern (of varying rates of decline and increase for urban and rural fertility levels in the same division suggests that perhaps flco .hwoaofioom Mo unmauummmo .GOwumuummmfic .n.nm wonmwfinamczv gmwumum vmuficp «Lu cfl mmucmummmwo >uwafluumm cmnua cw wuouUMh 0cm monouas .wsnmmm .0 :muasm "ouuSOm .cowuwnwwmc swans 0H0 so Momma. ... ... ... 0.0 I m.~ I ... m.5 I 0.0 «.0 I 0.0 0H0HI000H ... ... ~.N I 0.m I 5.~ I 0.0 I m.0 I H.0 I 0.HHI 0.0 I 0N0HI0H0H ... ... 0.0HI 0.0 I 5.5 I H.H «.0 I 0.0HI 0.0HI 0.0 I omwalomwd ... ... N.~ 0.0 I 0.N I 0.0HI 0.maI 0.0 I 0.0 I 0.0 I 000HI000H ... ... 0.0mI m.0mI 0.0NI 5.00I 0.50I 0.0mI ~.0~I 0.HmI 0H0HI000A 0.0 I 0.0 I 0.0HI «.0 I 0.0 I 0.0 I 0.0 I 0.0 0.0 0.0 I 0~0HI0H0H 0.0HI 0.HHI ~.~HI 5.5 I 0.NHI 0.maI 0.0 I «.maI H.0HI 0.HHI om0HI0~0H H.0 I 5.0 I n.0HI 0.5aI 0.0HI 0.~HI 0.HHI 0.N~I H.0HI 0.0HI 000HI000H 0.0m n.5H 0.0a H.~H 0.0a 0.00 0.5m 0.00 H.0m «.mu 000HI000H ~.0H 0.0a 5.0 0.H I 0.0 N.0H 0.0H 0.0m 0.00 0.Ha «000HI000H 0.NH 0.NH 0.0 5.m I 0.H I 5.0a 0.0a «.ma 0.0m H.0 000HI000~ Dammumm cwmunscx Hmuucwo Hmuucao uwuzmau< Hmuucmo Hmuucoo oquMHut unadmcm mmuwum coduum susom amok nusom uwmm nusom :uuoz ummz nuuoz ummm manna: 302 cmuwcn coma 0» oHOH cam oewa o» coma "Hanan .mcoflmfi>«w 0cm cowum: an .OHO mumma 00 Cu 0N :mEos 000:3 000.a “on 0H0 mumwx 0 Moons :muvawzu mo uonfiac mo moansu ommucoouwm .m manna ... ... ... ... 5.0 ... ... 0.0 ~.~ 0.0 camanomH ... ... H.0H ~.0HI 0.0 I ... 5.0HI 0.0 I 0.0 I 5.5 I 0~0HI0H0H ... ... m.H 0.0NI 0.~HI ... H.0HI 0.0HI 0.0HI 0.0HI 000HI0~0H ... ... 0.0 I 0.0 I 0.0 m.00I 0.5 I 0.H I 0.0 I 0.H I 000HI000H ... ... 0.00I 0.00I 0.50I 0.00I H.00I 0.00I 0.0NI H.00I 0H0HI000H 0.0 I 0.0 5.HdI 0.0 I 0.0 I n.~ I «.0 ~.H 0.0 0.0 0~0HI0H0H 0.AHI 0.0I 0.5 I H.0 I 0.NHI m.NHI 0.5HI 0.0mI 0.0HI 0.5HI 000HI0~0H 0.5I 0.0I 0.0HI 0.0HI 0.00I ~.HHI 0.0HI 0.0nl 0.0NI 0.0HI 000HI000H 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.50 0.00 0.00 0.H0 0.H0 0.00 000HI000H 0.Nm H.5N 0.0m m.m~ 0.00 0.00 0.50 0.Nm 0.00 m.Nm a000HI000H m.0~ 5.0m 0.m~ m.HN 0.0m 0.00 0.00 «.00 0.Hm 0.0a 000HI000H Ouuwowm canvases Hmuucoo Hauuaou caucmau< Hmuucoo Hmuucoo oauamuut ucsdmnm uouuum noduom nusom you: suaom uumm £9900 suuoz no»: :quZ 9000 Genoa: 302 vuuwap 000a 0» 0H0~ can 000A 00 000A “sunk: .mco«o«>«c 0:0 c0090: an .vao uuuo0 00 0» 0m :0393 wads} 000.H “am one munch 0 Moon: couvauso no moans: no omcanu amoucoouom .m «Haws 24 .00 manme .AN00H .oomoflzu mo xuwmum>flca .xmoaofioom 00 ucmfiuummmo .COMumuuwmmwc .0.:m uwnmwanaacdv :moumum cmuflcb 0:0 :0 mmucmummwflo xuwaauumm gangs :0 muouumm 0cm mccwu9= .wfinwmm .m acadnw "mousom .cowuwcwwmc away: 000 :0 00mmm¢ ... ... ... 0.0 ... ... N.0A N.0 H.0 000A ... ... N.NN 0.0 0.0 ... 0.0 0.HH 0.00 0.5 0HOH ... ... N.0H 0.0 0.0 ... N.a 0.HH 0.00 N.5 0NOH ... ... 5.0M 0.H 0.0 0.0 0.N 0.0H 0.0a 0.0 000d ... ... 0.0m H.N 5.5 0.0 0.0 H.0H 0.0M 0.0a 000a 0.00 0.00 0.NN 5.0a 0.00 0.00 5.00 0.05 0.05 5.00 000A 0.00 0.00 0.0m 0.0N 0.H0 5.50 0.00 0.05 0.05 N.H0 0NOH 0.00 0.00 0.00 H.0N 0.00 0.H0 0.00 5.55 0.55 N.00 000A 0.00 5.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05 H.05 0.00 000A 0.00 n.00 H.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.05 0.00 #0000 0.05 0.00 0.00 H.00 0.00 0.~0 5.00 0.00 «.05 0.00 0000 H.H0 H.50 5.50 0.00 0.50 0.00 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.00 000A UMMHUmm camucsoz Hmuucmo Hmuucoo caucmau< amuucoo Hmuucmo Uuucmaud usuamcu nuumum Mama £9500 anus £u500 uamm zusom nuuoz 9003 auuoz ummu mavcfiz 302 vouwsp 0000 cu 0H0H 0:0 000A 0» 000A .nco«n«>«0 was amumum couanb aaonwauuucoo ham swans Gawunnamom Havou we omoucuouum .0 manna , a . 'Ou:'t:l\n «0 5n; ‘5 ’ ‘0‘ ‘*..‘.“§\ 9‘ s . . _ - ~ ‘0» ..-. .';: " '- 5 _J ““O b§~ ‘..~ v‘ . D ‘ "‘ ‘I-a .‘Vb ‘ ‘ n-0y--'~_ . r > ‘ _ - ‘ s. .0._,___ V. ..- . O . ‘ ....\ . ‘ ‘ - ‘ -. 0‘. .....-.-. -“ - ‘v- . , ' 0-,. - . ‘ - . ~ .... "-As. . .... - u “- --.v: 'v h~-‘-_. __ v.-- -- -..- . . ‘ ~"" r-.. . - t -..‘v‘ .5 . O 'O- ‘ : --v“ v , ... ". - ..n - ‘0 -. - . ._. C -. y- ‘. ,“ ‘ ‘ . ..-._- .-_ .2». ‘ ‘ --_._‘- ~‘I- . _ ' -._.- _v.. .. h‘ ' 5““ 0.- -.:, ~~ _ w.‘ o "v. - _‘ . ._‘ . ..‘ \ "—-.- .‘ ‘ :v- . .. “.- .. ‘°.. ~- I “V". .5- " - ‘c .2... 5." . r u ‘ . "n ~‘A ._ _ "l n ‘ ."s. . v_. . ~§~ “A“. “ U . ‘. ~ '~--; ' - - -‘v‘ ... . ’ .. , .. . me -~»-. 1; ...- _ s~‘ , II .‘I' '\ ;. . ..- s. ‘ . ‘ '0 .\C‘ .' ‘, . 0 ’§ ‘- 'v- . a -.. . .‘,‘ \' c s. .. N . ‘- . 5 “' .1 '- ‘b . .- u. .. ~ Q ‘-. -u‘; “ V " ’av ' § - ‘§ -< h.‘ V. Iv 0“... ‘ 0 . b ‘0 . ‘1. s ...-0‘ ‘5 '- s " ,..- 0‘. -. - a‘ '. ‘\ 0‘ .V. ‘I H‘ \ ‘Nv‘ " v I‘. . . ‘.~Dp .\ -- ‘ ‘ V‘ " § .l ‘I ...; .‘ ‘ 'u\ \ '1 *. . a, s " ‘s 25 comparison of these tables will reveal certain irregular- ities in the usually hypothesized association of urbaniza— tion and fertility decline. The "baby boom" era of 1940—60 is perhaps the most obvious descrepancy. Urban and rural fertility ratios both have increased significantly since 1940, while the nation and all divisions have continued to ‘become more urban. Likewise, between 1910 and 1920 there “ms very rapid urbanization of the population, but during this period there were slight increases in the urban fertil— ity ratio of the nation and four divisions (New England, Bfiddle Atlantic, East North Central, Mountain), and in the rural fertility ratios of two divisions (New England, Middle .Atlantic). During some of the very early decades of the 1800's urban and rural fertility fell quite rapidly, even ‘though the extent of urbanization was quite modest. Between 1810 and 1820 there was no increase in the proportion of urban population, rather there was a slight decrease, but both the urban and the rural fertility ratios decreased substantially. During the decade 1930-1940 little increase occurred in the proportion of the population urban, but declines in fertility ratios were quite significant for both urban and rural populations. From the scrutiny of these figures the fact becomes clear that over the past century and a half in the nine geo— graphic divisions of the nation there is not merely 222 pattern of the relationship of urbanization and fertility trends, but there is evidence of four. According to Hashmi 26 1:?rese are (l) fertility decrease with increasing urbaniza- t:itnn (2) fertility decrease with decreasing urbanization, (13) fertility increase with increasing urbanization and (4) fertility increase with decreasing urbanization.35 The :Eirst of these patterns is the expected inverse relationship ()f fertility and urbanization. It is found frequently in 130th the urban and rural populations of the divisions. The ssecond pattern is associated with the economic depression of t:he 1930's. With decreases in urbanization for 1930—1940, ifour divisions (New England, Middle Atlantic, East North (Zentral, Pacific) indicate a parallel decrease in both urban 21nd rural fertility ratios. This pattern occurred also for 130th ratios in the West South Central division between 1840— 31910 and the Middle Atlantic between 1810-1820 and for the Irural fertility ratio in the West South Central between 1810— 1820. The third pattern is best exemplified by the "baby boom" period since 1940. The upsurge of both urban and rural fertility ratios in this period is a direct contradic- tion of the expected pattern of decreasing fertility with Lubanization. A similar pattern, though less spectacular and widespread, occurred among some of the divisions during the 1910—1920 decade, again for both urban and rural fertil— ity. Fertility levels indicate accretion during moderate urbanization between 1810-1820 in the urban population for 3SIbid., p. 44. 27 'tlne nation and New England, Middle Atlantic, and South Zthlantic divisions and the rural population for the nation zxnd Middle.Atlantic division. In addition there were a few :isolated cases which occurred in the 19th century for urban Eind rural fertility levels. The fourth pattern, decreasing :Eertility and increasing urbanization, is rare. Omitting czases which occurred between 1940 and 1950 because of the jLnadequacy of the old definition of urban leaves the single zincident of urban fertility in the West South Central divi- ssion for 1810—1820. On the basis of these findings Hashmi czoncludes that "urban fertility has not responded unilater- Eilly to progressive urbanization at any time in the past."36 st far as that goes, neither has rural fertility reflected a.unilateral pattern of change with urbanization. These fluctuations in urban and rural fertility suggest that fac- tors other than urbanization are operative within both pop- ulations. These other factors must be identified and in- vestigated in order to better understand fertility varia— tions and trends for both urban and rural areas. Another line of analysis of the historical changes in the urban-rural fertility differential is to consider independently the magnitude of the gap between the fertility ratios of the residential populations. Are urban and rural fertility levels approaching unity and, if so, what has been 36Ibid., p. 44. ...‘s-n 4--...v -.~‘ q n - o-I' . . a n ‘n . - .. , ... _‘_ " nu- -... . ~i -~¢'- . I'. ‘ I .“ u \ ...- I. t -“- -. I II 28 ‘tlue pattern of change in closing the gap and what is the crurrent magnitude of this gap? One measure of this gap is cibtained by considering the absolute differences between Ilrban and rural fertility levels at given points in time. TPable 5 provides this information by decade for the nation 21nd the geographical divisions. The table shows that for tzhe nation as a whole there were greater urban—rural differ- eances in fertility during the period 1800-1840 than in the I;eriods 1910-1940 and 1940-1960. Although there was a \Midening trend from 1810 to 1830, as urban fertility ratios rdeclined by more points than rural ratios, absolute differ- eances in urban—rural fertility have narrowed considerably <3ver the years. This trend continued through 1960 in spite <3f the increases in both urban and rural fertility ratios during the period 1940-1960. The largest gap between urban— rural fertility appears in 1830, an absolute difference of 481, and the smallest in 1960 with a gap of only 111. The same pattern as found in the national figures applies also to the divisions, with some deviations, of course. Nevertheless all divisions but New England have reached the point of smallest absolute differences between urban and rural fertility ratios by 1960. Through 1940 New England and Middle Atlantic, the more progressively urbaniz- ing divisions, maintained the lowest absolute differences between urban and rural fertility. By 1960 they represent the largest differences among the divisions, the other 299 .H manme ca co>flm moflumu >uflawuumu co comma :oHumuamEou "woudom .cowuwcwmwc :mnud 0H0 :0 commma ... ... ... ... mo. ... ... «0. m5. #0. coma ... ... 5v. m5. mo. ... Vb. mm. mh. mo. Gama ... ... hm. no. no. ... mm. mm. om. mo. ONmH ... ... 00. mm. mo. 00. Ho. 09. Nb. ow. omwd ... ... hm. co. mm. mv. mo. Ah. vb. N0. ova mm. mm. mm. Hm. vm. cm. ch. 05. mm. cm. chH hm. mm. ¢m. Nm. cm. cm. m5. VF. mm. mm. ONmH 00. cm. hm. mm. Vm. mm. 00. mo. hh. cm. OmmH Ac. mm. mm. am. am. cc. Ho. mo. Nb. on. cvma mn. mm. hh. mm. mm. mh. Nb. N5. 05. Ah. «cmmH mm. co. ch. mm. mm. vs. ms. N5. 55. Nb. cmmH *0. mm. Nc. mm. mm. om. mm. cm. Vm. mm. omma wawumm cwmucsoz Hmuucwu Hmuucoo Uwucmaum Hmuucmo Hmuucmo Uwucmaum panacea moumum Ham» nuaom ummz Lusom ummm nusom :uuoz umoz nuuoz ummm macpqz 3oz couwcb coma 0» chH can cvma 0» coma uncofimu>fic can sedan: >n .GHO whack we Ou cN :oEO3 «UMSB ccc.H umm pao muwo» m “macs coupawno mo Hones: Hmuau mo COMHHOQOHQ m an cmnub .c manna ... ... ... ... fiom ... ... hmv mmN fihv ocmH ... ... 0mm mmm Adv ... cmv ON¢ VMN mN¢ OHmH ... ... cmc QVm va ... 5mm mmm mod mfiv ONQH ... ... wmm moo N¢¢ NNm ehm wbm hMN Hmv Ommd ... ... mvc mow ma¢ cub cm¢ mmN ch mm¢ cfimH cmN vvm m5? mm¢ oc¢ wmm NON mmH 0c mam OHmH mmN hmm mum mov mmm mmN mmH th NOH MFN ONmH HON VQN mam 5cm m¢m m¢N ch ¢cN «NH chN Ommd mmH mMN mVN mam HON vHN bON Aha NNH OGN cvmd vhH one HOH cNN hNN me mmH Goa QNH «ca acmma NwH NBA and NMN mHN mma HmH med med mad cmmd mm FHA mm mm Na baa ccH wVH mHH HHH coma vaudumm canvases Hauucoo Hmuucoo ofiusmaum Hmuucoc Hmuucoc caucmaum pamamcm aouaum ummw susom um03 :usom uunm gusom :uuoz umo3 suuoz ummm macnwz 302 Quads: coma 0» cam” can oemfl ou coma "mcoaua>«c can no«ua: an .cdo anon» v¢ cu cw COED: 09%;: ccc.a Hon vac chaos m umpsn couoawzu mo amass: Hmuauucmnun :4 noucououuao ovaaownd .m canoe >.. ..-.- . \ flu.-.y..~ 'n-‘IO 9: ,- - .‘.>.I-. l a o '4. 1.0-.. ,.. . -~-v~—q- - .. .. ......-.___, 0 "-v -a I‘.. In... 'u-. ‘.5 — 0 . v..- ._'~t ~- . .- -_,_‘ § ‘ n ‘D .n~ h " ».- q... u . -,‘ ... ~ . ‘u ‘- ‘. ‘u o.( n. § . '- : ' ~ 5 . . . ~.. tl A _ b ‘ -.fi -__ ‘Q . ~.' I .‘~. ‘0 - - -"_\ P. '5 'L i . ‘S'N. -. h’.‘ ‘ b h. . ’0 ‘7 .: . . s .. ‘ r .. ‘O - .. . ‘I "\ l Arv‘ ‘ v . _ , n -.- I \ ' i . v .. . 'I I ‘| a K. -. ‘ S Q" ‘ .. . - ._ \ ‘ II ._ _ .\ a“ s-\ . v _ ~ 3 . . . ‘\ C . a .. . A J“ . _. . .- \ . 3O éLivisions having dwindled their differences to lower levels. Generally speaking, however, Table 5 tends to show clearly izhat during the 19th century there were larger urban—rural J:‘esents two sets of rank—order correlations for the nation 211:1d its divisions. The first set of correlations indicates t1118 level of association between changes in percent urban EiIld the changes in absolute differences in urban—rural fer— ‘tdility ratios from 1800 to 1960. The second set of correla- tlions indicates the level of association between percent xxrban and the magnitude of the urban—rural differential Ineasured by relative prOportion. Hashmi concluded that 11rbanization and the decline of absolute differences of urban 21nd rural fertility ratios were highly related. Table 7 loears this conclusion out. The nation indicates a very high Irank—order correlation of -.93 while all the divisions also Skumlhigh negative correlations of varying degree. Hence, Ifiashmi is correct when he states that urbanization is only iassociated with the long-term decline of absolute differences 7between urban and rural fertility but not the level or direc- tion. The measure of urban fertility as a prOportion of rural fertility, it can be said, is more sensitive to the lfiivel and direction of fertility change. For example, this measure does respond to the change in direction of fertility 1eVels during the 1940—1960 "baby boom." If, however, urban andrural fertility ratios had not increased for 1940—1960, but had declined, it would have been possible for the size 0f the absolute difference between the two ratios to remain 'the same, quite independent of the direction of change in the 33 \ frzable 7. Rank order correlations of percentage of total population urban with absolute differences in urban—rural fertility ratios and urban to rural fertility ratios; for conterminous United States and divisions: 1800-1840 and 1910-1960 ‘ Area rho of rho of % Urban and % Urban and Absolute Urban Differences in As a Proportion Urban—Rural White of Rural White Fertility Ratios Fertility Ratios IJnited States -.93 -.02 E New England —.68 +.27 Ddiddle Atlantic —.87 +.30 IEast North Central -.83 +.30 West North Central -.98 +.64 South Atlantic —.94 -.05 East South Central -.71 —.03 West South Central —.92 +.55 Mountain —l.00 +.99 Pacific —l.00 +1.00 <3Omputations of rank-order correlations based on Tables 4, 5 and 6. Formula used: rho = l — 7‘” 6ZD2 N(N2 — 1) .\ v 34 ‘ITEELtios themselves. In comparison the measure of relative {patroportion of urban to rural fertility ratios would have situown a lower value if both ratios had continued to decline I:um zuwwx cam .mamomm cmaad .b .hmzmnumm mama "muusom H.H~ o.h~ H.md s.m~ ¢.om m.m~ 0mm.~ mm~.~ mm~.H Hum.~ mos.~ mo¢.H mmo.m eom.~ o~m.~ oauaoam m.n~ o.- m.oH m.m~ ~.H~ o.o~ ooh.~ omm.~ on.H ~Sm...” oom.~ o~m.~ msv.n had.n omm.~ camucso: m.- m.v~ 5.6H o.s~ v.mH m.H~ nmm.~ oov.~ ¢-.a maa.m omn.~ a~¢.a m-.m wom.~ mmv.H anuunuo canon yum: o.~m m.m~ m.m~ m.mm o.- n.m~ Ho¢.~ om~.~ mHH.H mmq.m mom.~ Hmm.~ oom.m smo.~ mm~.H Hmuusoo nusom ammo m.m~ v.vH ~.n~ m.oe v.- ¢.¢H mh~.~ «NH.~ mmo.a wmm.~ mwe.~ ao~.a mo~.m mom.~ mm~.H Unusuaua nunom m.nH m.m~ o.mH n.s~ o.- ~.H~ mam.~ mmv.~ mom.a Hmo.m omn.~ mmm.a mm~.m mpm.~ mm¢.~ Hauucoo nuuoz um»: ¢.hd o.m~ $.5H o.Hm m.¢~ m.na vmv.m vmm.~ ma~.H maa.~ mum.~ om¢.~ mm~.n nmm.~ omv.a Hauunoo suuoz «mam ~.na m.o~ m.m~ m.av H.mm 5.0m mn~.~ emo.~ omo.~ moo.~ mme.~ vmm.a HH~.m mam.~ -¢.~ ufiucwaua manna: s.m o.o~ m.¢~ o.am m.~m m.om Hm¢.~ oo~.~ oma.~ ome.~ om¢.~ mam.a oo~.m mam.~ oom.~ camamcm 302 o.o~ ~.¢H o.o~ m.mm ¢.m~ o.o~ woe.~ oo~.~ mBH.H mom.~ oam.~ ohm.H ~o~.m nwm.~ woe.” nuumum amass: ¢¢lmm #mlmN vNImH fivimm VMImN lemH ¢¢Imm enlmN GNImH ¢¢lmm ¢MImN VNImH ¢¢Imm GmlmN VNImH nmnub mowmuxm mama cmnub mcwmoxm oumm swan: EHmtn:OZtamusm Bumhldmuflm BumhInOZUHmusm unmouom Bummldmusm unwouwm we: can wocmcwmmm an uumm mumawuuom ouwsz.o>quHSEbo Goad .ndOfl0dhav can aouuum cuuucb uuonwauoucou wow mom can oococwmou >8 c0203 over: poauumaluubm ccc.H hon anon uu>o suuwddsu HO Hun-52 .0 means 38 t:he nation and its nine divisions in 1960 the cumulative ‘Nhite fertility rate, i.e., the number of children ever born jper 1,000 ever-married white women, for all three residence categories (rural—farm, rural-nonfarm, urban) by broad age divisions of the women's reproductive period (15-24, 25-34, 35-44). In contrast with the trend analysis fertility data discussed previously, here we are (1) using a different mea— sure of fertility, children ever born, which is actually a measure of average number of children per married white woman, (2) including data for fertility levels for three residential categories rather than the simple dichotomy of rural-urban, and (3) inserting a control for age of women. It is of Special import to consider at this point cumulative fertility rates by division, residence and age categories for 1960, since these are the products of the differential fertility patterns which will be investigated in this study. When we consider internal variation of fertility levels for residence groups later, the cumulative fertility rate will be the measure employed. Table 8 not only exhibits a consistent and sub- stantial rural-urban fertility differential for 1960, but also sizeable intra-residence group differences among the divisions. Among all three age groups the number of chil- dren ever born per 1,000 ever-married rural-farm white women in the nation as a whole ranged from 20 to 36 percent above that for urban white women. For rural-nonfarm white women 39 tzhis rate ranged from 14 to 21 percent above urban white vvqmen. In comparing rural—farm and rural—nonfarm white fertility rates, however, the differences are small (rural- farm rates ranging from 3 to 12 percent above rural—nonfarm fertility rates). The pattern for the nation, then, is one of high cumulative fertility rates for the rural—farm popu- lation, intermediate for rural-nonfarm, and low for urban. Furthermore, fertility rates are more similar for the two rural residence groups than either rural residence group is to the urban group. For white women ages 35 to 44 the dif— ference in rural-farm and urban fertility rates is 854, rural—nonfarm and urban 495, and rural—farm and rural— nonfarm 359. The pattern of high rural-farm, intermediate rural-nonfarm and low urban fertility is repeated with few exceptions by the nine divisions of the nation in 1960. The exceptions to this pattern are all instances where the rural-nonfarm fertility level exceeded the rural—farm, but in no case does the urban level exceed that of either rural pOpulation, farm or nonfarm. The magnitude of the fertil— ity differential between white rural-farm and urban resi- dence groups for women age 15 to 24 ranges from 14 percent in the South Atlantic divisions to 31 percent in the Middle Atlantic above the fertility rate for white urban women at this age. In this age group and women ages 25 to 34, there is some indication that the rural-farm and urban fertility .-+- .v-‘ v~- | 9. 's ‘A v ..v «I' (1’ (I! A—o—A-‘HfiA 4o differential is largest in the more urban divisions and leaast in the less urban divisions. Rural-farm fertility leavels for women 25 to 34 range in excess of urban fertility firom a high of 35 percent in the Middle Atlantic to a low of 153 percent in the West South Central. For the age group of 35 to 44, an age group of women for whom childbearing is near completion and provides some indication of complete fertility levels for the p0pulation, rural—farm fertility exceeds urban fertility within a range of 41 percent for Middle Atlantic and South Atlantic to 26 percent in the Mountain division. To conclude this discussion on the rural-farm and urban differential, it might be said that insofar as the age groups of married women represent current and completed fertility, there is evidence of a continuation of shrinking differentials. However, considering that the more urban divisions reveal the largest gaps between rural— farm and urban fertility, as the nation becomes progressively more urban, the differential should eXpand rather than con- tract. This same pattern is supported by previously dis- cussed trend data and the impact of upsurging fertility levels during 1940-1960 on the urban—rural differential. The size of the fertility differential between rural-nonfarm and urban fertility, when compared among age cohorts of women, seems also to show a continuation toward convergence, although the variation among divisions is not as extreme as in the rural-farm populations of the divisions. 41 Threea exceptions are New England, Middle Atlantic, and East North.Central divisions which are highly urbanized. The differential seems to be eXpanding in these divisions. Rural-nonfarm fertility for women 15 to 24 ranges from 15 percent above the urban rate in New England and South Atlantic to 24 percent in the Middle Atlantic and for women 25 to 34 from a low of 10 percent above urban in New England to 18 percent in the East South Central. Rural-nonfarm fer- tility for women 35 to 44 exceeds the urban level by only 9 percent in New England and 33 percent in the East South Central division. With reSpect to the rural-nonfarm and urban pOpulations it is more difficult to generalize that the more urban divisions reflect fertility differentials than the less urban divisions since the ranges are rela- tively small. There is considerable amount of variation within residence groups when comparisons are made among divisions. White women residing in the Mountain division, for each age and residence group, show higher fertility levels than com- parable white women in any other division. Within the rural-farm pOpulation the average number of children per white married woman 15 to 24 ranges from 1.6 in the Mountain division to 1.2 in the South Atlantic. This average for women 35 to 44 ranges from 3.5 in the Mountain division to 3.0 for Pacific. For rural-nonfarm women 15 to 24 the average number of children ranges from a low of 1.3 in South Atlantic to a high of 1.5. For women 35 to 44 New England 42 and Ddiddle Atlantic divisions are low with an average of 2.7 children, Mountain is high at 3.3. For urban women 15 to 24 Middle Atlantic, South Atlantic and East South Central all have an average of 1.1 children per white married woman and Mountain has the high average of 1.3. Urban completed fertility levels range from a low of 2.3 for Middle.Atlantic, South Atlantic, and Pacific, to a high of 2.8 in the Mountain division. Hence, not only is there Continuing urban-rural fertility differential existing among all divisions of the United States, but there is also a con- siderable amount of variation in fertility levels within the same residence group among the various divisions due par- tially to the varying degrees of urbanization which exists among these divisions. These data suggest that if one is to investigate the internal variation of fertility within residence groups, the analysis should control for divisional variation of fertility levels at the same time. The fact that this study intends to look "within" the fertility pattern of each residence group, for the nation and for each geographic division, raises the question of the homogeneity of fertility levels in each residence group. A look "within" assumes that there is variation of fertility levels to be eXplained or accounted for. If com— plete homogeneity existed within residence groups, i.e., if all rural-farm women produced very close to the same number of children within the same division, there could be no 43 expljanation of variation for the rural-farm population. However homogeneity does not exist for fertility levels of residence groups even when controlling for divisional effects. Table 9 is a rough attempt to portray and facil— itate the visualization of variation that does exist among Cumulative fertility levels (measured as number of children ever-born per 1,000 ever-married white women age 15 to 44) for residential parts of counties in conterminous United States and the nine divisions. The already established fattern of the tendency of high fertility levels in rural— farm areas, intermediate in rural—nonfarm, and low in urban areas is easily observed in the table, as well as the fact that among the various divisions there are considerable differences in the pattern and extent of variation of fer- tility levels within each of the residence groups. Never- theless what this table attempts to establish is the fact that there is a significant amount of variation of fertility levels among residential parts of counties respectively even within each of the divisions. Although we are not using a specific measure of variation, percentage distributions can give a rough indication of clustering or scattering of fer- tility levels within rural—farm, rural—nonfarm and urban pOpulations. An eyeball analysis of Table 9 tells us that fertility rates of urban parts of counties have a greater tendency to "bunch up" than rural-nonfarm and rural-farm rates. In other words, there is relatively less variation ,_ .... ~. .- . ... v. . . , 44 Table 9. Percentage distribution of urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm parts of counties Ly children ever born per 1,000 ever-married white women age 15-44 for conterminous United States and divisions: 1960 Children Ever Born per 1,000 Ever-Married White Women 15-44 Less Than 3,500 2,000 2,000-2,499 2,500-2,999 3,000-3,499 or Over Total NO. % N0. % NO. % NO 0 % NO. % NO. ‘7’: URBAN United States 407 19.2 1,387 65.2 303 14.3 23 1.1 5 0.2 2,124 100 N9W’England 0 0.0 55 93.2 4 6.8 0 0.0 0 0.0 59 100 Middle Atlantic 23 16.1 118 82.5 2 1.4 0 0.0 0 0.0 143 100 East North Central 21 5.7 286 77.5 60 16.3 2 0.5 0 0.0 369 100 West North Central 37 10.8 213 61.8 90 26.2 4 1.2 0 0.0 344 100 South Atlantic 152 40.6 217 58.1 5 1.3 0 0.0 0 0.0 374 100 East South Central 101 44.7 117 51.8 8 3.5 8 0.0 0 0.0 226 100 West South Central 66 19.1 215 62.1 55 15.9 6 1.7 4 1.2 346 100 Mountain 3 2.0 72 47.0 67 43.8 10 6.5 1 0.7 153 100 Pacific 4 3.6 94 85.5 12 10.9 0 0.0 0 0.0 110 100 RURAL-NONFARM thuted States 59 2.0 1,385 46.2 1,313 43.8 202 6.8 37 1.2 2,996 100 New England 0 0.0 40 60.6 24 36.4 1 1.5 1 1.5 66 100 Mimfle Atlantic 2 1.4 97 68.3 43 30.3 0 0.0 0 0.0 142 100 East North Central 2 0.5 182 41.8 236 54.3 15 3.4 0 0.0 435 100 West North Central 6 1.0 211 35.5 325 54.6 51 8.6 2 0.3 595 100 South Atlantic 27 4.9 358 65.5 138 25.2 24 4.4 0 0.0 547 100 East South Central 8 2.2 198 54.9 123 34.1 24 6.6 8 2.2 361 100 west South Central 6 1.3 187 41.0 223 48.9 29 6.4 11 2.4 456 100 Mountain 7 2.7 58 22.1 126 47.8 57 21.7 15 5.7 263 100 Pacific 1 0.8 54 41.2 75 57.2 1 0.8 0 0.0 131 100 RURAL-FARM United States 17 0.6 481 17.7 1,438 53.1 618 22.8 158 5.8 2,712 100 New England 0 0.0 12 20.7 27 46.6 18 31.0 1 1.7 58 100 Middle Atlantic 2 1.6 27 21.3 71 55.8 25 19.7 2 1.6 127 100 East North Central 0 0.0 53 12.7 225 53.8 106 25.4 34 8.1 418 100 West North Central 1 0.2 71 11.8 321 53.2 173 28.7 37 6.1 603 100 South Atlantic 8 1.8 127 28.1 238 52.7 63 13.9 16 3.5 452 100 East South Central 2 0.6 70 20.1 187 53.5 70 20.1 20 5.7 349 100 West South Central 2 0.5 88 22.2 202 50.8 86 21.7 19 4.8 397 100 Mountain 1 0.5 15 7.7 91 47.0 58 29.9 29 14.9 194 100 Pacific 1 0.9 18 15.8 76 66.6 19 16.7 0 0.0 114 100 p‘ nob‘ .nv-"' , - ...d'l ...‘aoOQ --..~ I no...— 0 y. . ‘k— (I) ‘Vfl 45 hazaccount for within urban fertility. In comparison, ruralrfhrm fertility reveals the largest amount of relative variation among residence groups. It is interesting to note that even within the urban residence category, the divisions Which have the smallest variation are those which are more urbanized. New England, Middle Atlantic and Pacific divi— sions have 93 percent, 83 percent, and 85 percent of their urban parts of counties reSpectively falling within the Cumulative fertility range of 2,000 to 2,499. Over half (51 percent) of the urban parts of counties in the Mountain division have fertility rates of over 2,500. Although rural— farm fertility levels reveal the wider variation than each of the other residence groups, the distribution patterns for rural—farm fertility seems to be more consistent among the divisions than urban or rural-nonfarm fertility. Although the amount of variation may have something to say about the success of accounting for urban vis—a-vis rural-farm fertil- ity fluctuations, given the same number of variables, the point to be stressed here is that there remains a consider- able amount of variation to be accounted for within residence groups of the United States. C. L N. .. n..., *--.vo . . . 5p. -.--A-: '. .._~ ... ‘:c6 ‘ ..11. . ‘ n - Q ‘ I -,.. ..., “- — Q -. h. . ..- . ‘\.‘, u 0‘ 4" ~ ‘ .0 u ‘u. . t‘ - ‘5 ‘u ‘n . . ‘-“ fi .. <'. . \- ‘ s " q .t ‘ . a . v - ‘ ... v- ‘I ... ‘ - ... : ~h \ . . ‘ ~ . -- . a c . a--~ I - - 2. ~ . .__ . -. s- . ‘s - \‘. I ’. ._ , . . - ¥ .- p n .. 5 u '- .. . U. ‘ I . . § \ \ .- .A.‘ Q. ' \ e— t ' v . O “. U y r ‘\ I lu'. ‘ 46 The Goldberg Hypothesis In concluding this discussion of trends and current status of the urban—rural differential in fertility, it would not be complete without taking into account a confound- ing issue that has cropped up in recent studies.40 We may call this the "Goldberg hypothesis," although others have contributed to the analysis of this problem as well. The Goldberg hypothesis emanates from the recent finding that "farm background" over and above the more traditional "cur- rent residence" variables (urban, rural—nonfarm, rural-farm) is a significant determinant of the rural-urban fertility differential. Briefly the hypothesis states that the inverse relationship of fertility and socio-economic status found in urban areas is the product of a large proportion of farm migrants which are diSproportionately concentrated in the lower socio—economic status categories of the urban pOpulation. The Freedmans estimated that in 1952 more than 40The major studies include David Goldberg, "The Fertility of Two Generation Urbanites," Population Studies, XII (March, 1959), 214—22; David Goldberg, "Another Look at the Indianapolis Fertility Data," 0p. cit.; Ronald Freedman and Deborah Freedman, "Farm-Related Elements in the Nonfarm POpulation," Rural Sociology; XXI (March, 1956), 50—61; Ronald Freedman and Doris P. Slesinger, "Fertility Differen- tials for the Indigenous Non—Farm Population of the United States," ngulation Studies, XV (November, 1961), 161-73; and Otis Dudley Duncan, "Farm Background and Differential Fertility," Demography, II (1965), 240—49. Also see a much earlier discussion of this problem in T. J. Woofter, "Trends in Rural and Urban Fertility Rates," Rural Sociology, XIII (March, 1948), 3-9. . .-v a “vi... 6... ._ ' ... ' ... - '2'~ . on. ‘ ' s D‘.'- 'u.. , c n ' . ‘ -“ I ..- .. .- . --’ . ‘u. '1.» ..- it... Q. ‘5 . ~~ . n..~ ‘- ‘§ 47 twicre as many farm-reared adults were living off the farm aScnthe farm in the United States and that one of every three adults living in a nonfarm place was reared on a farm.41 With reSpect to a number of variables the Freedmans found that the farm-reared pOpulation revealed relatively distinct distribution patterns in comparison with persons of the nonfarm pOpulation with no farm eXperience and that "the farm-reared have come into the nonfarm economy relatively poorly prepared from an educational point of view . . . [and] have tended to fill relatively low-status jobs and to earn low incomes."42 Goldberg argues that the study of Luban fertility differentials based on current residence categories will be complicated by the presence of rural elements in the urban population. He finds that the inverse relationship of fertility and socio—economic status is char— acteristic only of the rural migrants in the urban popula- tion, but not of the indigenous urban pOpulation.43 Fertil- ity behavior of farm migrants, then, is much different than indigenous urbanites in that farm migrants on the average had a significantly larger number of children than indigenous 41Ronald Freedman and Deborah Freedman, op. cit., 42Ibid., p. 54. 43David Goldberg, "The Fertility of Two Generation Urbanites," 0p. cit., and "Another Look at the Indianapolis Fertility Data," 0p. cit. ... . ,4] 48 Imbariites. This finding suggests that even within the urban residence category there are urban-rural differences which may complicate or mask over the relationship potentially characteristic of an indigenous urban population. These findings are especially relevant to our study Which will attempt to investigate the differential fertility patterns existent within each of the residence groups. Basically what this implies is that the fertility differen- tial patterns in the residence categories will not be as disshnilar as they potentially could be because of the con- fbunding effect of rural migration to urban and rural-non- farm areas. Except for Special surveys, in studies based on census data, which is the case of our study, it is impos- sible to differentiate within the residence categories between farm and nonfarm background. Since no measure of farm background is available it will be impossible to con- trol for the effects of migration between residence groups on internal fertility patterns. However, this does not render the present study invaluable or unreliable. There are perhaps many controls which should be made in such a study but for which data are lacking. Furthermore, there are reservations which could be stated at this point concerning the hypothesized effects of migration between residence categories on fertility patterns. Hashmi criticized the Goldberg hypothesis on four counts: (1) two-generation urbanites have a very different religious, 49 Iaativity, ethnic and educational background than more recent Inigrants and these were not fully controlled in making his comparisons; (2) fertility rates have fallen in rural areas as rapidly and as far as in urban areas, lagging only by a decade or two behind their urban rates; (3) there is no sociological rationale for such a persistence; rural culture is neither homogeneous nor especially resistent to change; (4) the recent "baby boom" has not been shown to be an out- break of rurality among urban pOpulations, but something which has been most pronounced among the most urbanized segments of the population.44 In addition, Grabill, Kiser and Whelpton provide some indication of the impact of the rural to urban shift of the population on the decline of national fertility levels from 1810 to 1940. Their table is reproduced here as Table 10. Generally for the nation the shift of the pOpulation to urban areas accounts for only 20 percent of the changes in national fertility and much less for changes in fertility levels of the divisions. This table seems to suggest that changes in urban and rural fer— tility per se account for most of the change in national and divisional fertility levels, but what factors account for changes within rural and urban fertility? We have already established the necessity of considering the internal pat- terns of fertility within residence populations. 44Sultan S. Hashmi, "Trends and Factors in Urban Fer- tility Differences in the United States," op. cit., p. 126. 50 Table 10. Urban-rural components of decline in number of children under 5 years old per 1,000 white women 20 to 44 years old, by divisions: 1810—1940 Percent Distribution Absolute Decline Due To Decline in Rural Decline Decline Children to Urban in in Per 1,000 Shift of Urban Rural Area Women Total Population Ratio Ratio United Statesa 890 100.0 20.2 23.8 56.0 New England 705 100.0 17.0 33.5 49.5 Middle Atlantic 969 100.0 20.4 30.7 48.9 E. N. Central 1,314 100.0 17.3 25.1 57.6 w. N. Centralb 1,379 100.0 3.9 26.9 69.2 South Atlantic 861 100.0 16.3 18.6 65.1 E. S. Central 1,161 100.0 9.9 15.3 74.9 W. S. Central 909 100.0 15.4 14.4 70.2 aIncludes the Mountain and Pacific Division in 1940 but not in 1810 when they were nonexistent. bThere was a nonexistent urban population in the West North Central Division in 1810 which of course had an indetermi— nate 0/0 ratio of children to women. It was necessary to assign some value to the ratio. The rural ratio was assigned. Source: Wilson H. Grabill, Clyde V. Kiser, P. K. Whelpton, The Fertility of American Women (New YOrk: John Wiley, 1958), p. 19. 51 In the same monograph Grabill, Kiser and Whelpton reproduce a table (Table 11) reflecting the fertility levels of the various types of migrants between residence cate— gories for 1940. These authors conclude that "in general, among ever-married women the fertility ratios of migrants tend to be intermediate between the fertility ratios of non- movers in the host area and the origin area."45 A closer look at the table indicates that actually the migrants resemble the fertility level of the host area more than the area of origin. For example, rural—farm to urban migrants show a fertility ratio of 407, rural-farm nonmovers 587, and urban nonmovers 334. Rural—farm to urban migrants have a fertility ratio differing from urban nonmovers by only 73 points, but by a 180 point difference when compared with rural—farm nonmovers. This is true when considering rural- nonfarm to urban migrants and rural—farm to rural-nonfarm migrants. The Goldberg hypothesis, on the basis of these findings, should be altered to take into consideration the fact that rural migrants in urban areas do not closely resemble in fertility behavior the population of their migra- tion origin. Since migrants tend to be selective in their fertility behavior, it might be concluded that rural migrants may have approached urban differential fertility patterns 45Wilson H. Grabill, Clyde V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, 0p. cit., p. 102. Table 11. 52 Urban-rural movement between 1935 and 1940 of native white women 15 to 49 years old, by marital status and number of own children under 5 years old in 1940 Ever Married Women 15 to Own Children Under 5 Per 1,000 Women Ever Married 49 Years Old Standardized Area and Mobility Status (000's) For Age Same House, 1935 and 1940 Urban in 1940 3,205 334 Rural nonfarm in 1940 1,368 457 Rural farm in 1940 1,677 587 IntracounpyyMovers (Interchange not tabulated) Urban in 1940 6,026 369 Rural nonfarm in 1940 1,958 501 Rural farm in 1940 1,583 643 Migrants Between Counties Urban to urban 1,358 314 Rural nonfarm to urban 345 344 Urban to rural nonfarm 553 400 Rural farm to urban 152 407 Rural nonfarm to rural nonfarm 273 464 Urban to rural farm 165 470 Rural farm to rural nonfarm 131 520 Rural nonfarm to rural farm 80 548 Rural farm to rural farm 294 659 Source: Wilson H. Grabill, Clyde V. Kiser, The Fertility of American Women (New York: Wiley, 1958), p. 101. and P. K. Whelpton, John 53 already previous to their actual migration to urban areas or that they acquired urban patterns soon after their arrival in urban areas. Furthermore, it might be inferred that due to a selective process in rural to urban migration the effect of this migration on urban fertility differentials may not be as great as hypothesized and that there still will be considerable differences in internal residential differential fertility patterns in Spite of the employment of current residence categories. Another consideration with respect to the impact of rural-urban migration on fertility patterns has to do with the magnitude of this migration by 1960 and thereafter. The massive farm-to-city migration of previous decades is no longer possible given the shrinking size of the rural, and eSpecially the rural—farm, population of the United States. While farm to urban migration will no doubt continue, those with farm backgrounds can have little numerical significance in the future. Bogue Speaking of farm migration and urban growth in 1950 said, "the rural population has diminished to a point where it can no longer be the major source of supply of urban growth. If cities are to grow in the future, natural increase probably must contribute by far the major I 46 I 0 share of the increase." Hence, an "indigenous urban 46Donald J. Bogue, "Urbanism in the United States, 1950," American Journal of Sociology. LX (March, 1955), 478. 54 population" may not be as far off as the Goldberg hypothesis seems to imply. Table 12 provides data for the percentage distribution of farm-born persons in the white farm and non- farm populations 18 years of age and over for the United States in 1958. To me these data suggest that the Size of the farm—born pOpulation in nonfarm areas is not consider- ably large, hence, nonfarm fertility patterns will not be greatly influenced by the presence of farm—born elements. Table 12. Distribution of the white civilian population 18 years of age and over, by residence, farm or non— farm birthplace, United States, 1958 Residence and Farm or Percentage Nonfarm Birthplace POpulation Distribution Total 98,014,000 100.0 Farm-born 22,199,000 22.6 Nonfarm—born 74,743,000 76.3 Not reported 1,072,000 1.1 Farm Residents 10,621,000 100.0 Farm-born 8,109,000 76.4 Nonfarm-born 2,512,000 23.6 Nonfarm Residents 86,321,000 100.0 Farm—born 14,090,000 16.3 Nonfarm-born 72,231,000 83.7 Source: Leo Schnore, "The Rural-Urban Variable: An Urban- ite's Perspective," Rural Sociology, XXXI, No. 2 (June, 1966), 138. 55 A final comment with respect to the Goldberg hypoth— esis pertains to the problem of investigating fertility behavior, which is the product of past eXperienceS, by the use of variables which reflect only current status of the pOpulation. This is a significant contribution of the writers connected with the Goldberg hypothesis. However, the problem not only pertains to current versus past res— idence, but to other variables employed as well in differ- ential fertility analysis. Duncan, who found that both farm background and educational attainment have a significant effect on fertility, points out that educational attainment (compared with such variables as income, occupation, and female labor force participation) is perhaps a more useful variable because it more accurately reflects the socio- economic situation of the couple at or before the time family growth was in process.47 It would be sound advice to attempt to build into the analysis of internal residential fertility variation, variables which tend to reflect past status rather current. This procedure could perhaps correct somewhat for the absence of a farm background variable in the analysis. 47Otis Dudley Duncan, "Farm Background and Differen- tial Fertility," 0p. cit., p. 242. ... ..~\ 56 The Causal Approach to Differential Fertilipy Westoff, in an article concerning the changing focus of differential fertility research,48 classified the develop- ment of fertility differential studies along three lines. First is the descriptive empirical studies which attempt to establish the nature of the relationships and to confirm their stability. Repetition of these studies served to measure time trends. However, Westoff declares that "these descriptive studies have been indespensable in defining the subject but, nevertheless, are only preliminary to the equally important task of ascertaining the causal complexes 49 involved." The second line of focus is classified as the evaluative approach. This approach predicted that the so— called "best" elements in society would die out because of under-reproduction. The third line, the causal approach, is the attempt to establish causes for differential fertility. Westoff hails the Indianapolis Study as "the first major study to test empirically substantive hypotheses which raise 50 In Spite of the fact that the India- the question 'why.'" napolis Study tested constructed hypotheses, it is question— able that the study could be classified "causal," since "the 48C. F. Westoff, "The Changing Focus of Differential Fertility Research: The Social Mobility Hypothesis," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXI (January, 1953), 24-38. 491bid., p. 25. 501bid., p. 25. a . ... 57 twenty—three hypotheses of the Indianapolis Study were not bound together by an integrating theory or organizing prin- ciple."51 Unfortunately, a majority of differential fertil— ity studies fall within the "descriptive empirical" category, many of these drawing upon census data. Considering the demand for the determination of the causal complexes of differential fertility, the present study is causal in sc0pe, in that it will begin from a theo— retical framework and will test hypotheses in Spite of the fact that it will draw upon census data. The necessity of such a study takes its cue from comments directed by Robert Gutman toward a recent study of differential fertility.52 Gutman sees a methodological deficiency in a good number of fertility differential studies, especially those based on census data, in that they tend to regard the groups whose fertility differences are being studied as "discrete uni— verses of facts." Summary measures are computed to describe what is going on in each of these universes with regard to fertility and then these measures are compared. To correct this Gutman calls for an approach "based on the assumption that the different subgroups of the population are really 51C. V. Kiser, "Methodological Lessons of the Indianapolis Fertility Study," Eugenics Quarterly, III (1956), 152-56; also see P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 96. 52Robert Gutman, "Comment on Kiser's Paper," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demogpaphic and Eco— nomic Change in Develpped Countries (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960), pp. 113-116. 58 samples drawn from a single universe of phenomena."53 Gut— man's eXpanded comments are as follows: It is only when we come to regard the study of differen— tial fertility as a means of approaching the larger question of the causes of fertility variation in the pOpulation as a whole that the assumption of samples drawn from a single universe becomes relevant. For in order to answer this question, it is essential to know not only that there p33 fertility differences by social group, but also to know the magnitude of these differ- ences and the direction in which they are moving. What is really crucial for understanding the role of occupa— tional, educational, nativity, residential, and racial factors as determinants of fertility is to ask what proportion of the total variance of fertility is the result of the differences in fertility between partic— ular groups. As I have indicated, there are studies in which the importance of this question has been recognized. But there are also many in which it has not, especially studies based on census data. . . . How often do we come across a statement which indicates the amount of the total variance which can be explained in terms of a particular coefficient of correlation? How often do we find statements which tell us what proportion of the total variance in a population is the consequence of group differences among the dimensions studied and what proportion is the result of differences within these groups? Even less often, and in the case of the numer- ous studies based on census data, never at all?54 In response to this justifiable indictment, the present study will apply multiple regression analysis to census data. Such application will not merely answer the charge of method— ological deficiency, but consequently should supply a signif- icant contribution to the analysis and eXplanation of differ- ential fertility. A multiple regression analysis will not 53Ibid., p. 113. 54l§iQ-. pp. 114-115 (italics mine). 59 only permit the determination of the proportion of variance in fertility levels explained by the independent variables, but also will determine the relative importance of the vari- ables included in the analysis in eXplaining fertility variance. In conventional differential fertility studies the researcher is limited with respect to the number of inde— pendent variables that can be related or cross—tabulated with the dependent variable. In the past, the researcher has usually correlated independent variables one at a time with fertility, although in some cases a limited number of control variables were inserted. For example, in the exhaus- tive study by Grabill, Kiser, and Whelpton55 which appeared as recently as 1958, the authors investigate fertility dif- ferentials under individual chapters, such as, residence, occupation, education, and other socio—economic factors. The problem of the intercorrelation of the socio—economic factors frequently used in conventional differential fertil- ity studies is described in the following quotation: In studying the various factors which differentiate the fertility of one group from another, it must be remembered that such factors are frequently closely inter-connected. For example, the variations of family size with income or occupation are closely linked because persons with high income are usually in certain occupational groups, and persons with small incomes with other occupational groups. Thus to say that fertility 55W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, The Fertility of American Women, op. cit. 6O varies with income and with occupation is to some extent merely6to describe the same phenomenon in two different ways. The employment of the statistical technique of multi— ple regression analysis, under certain assumptions, should minimize both the problem of inter-correlation and the lim- ited number of independent variables which can be handled at one time. Essentially, multiple regression analysis permits the manipulation of several independent variables at the same time while holding constant the effects of all indepen- dent variables except the one which is of concern. Thus, this study is "causal" in its intent, makes use of census data, and employs multiple regression analysis. Basic Design of the Study: Distributive Apppoach The object of this study is the investigation of inter-communipy_fertility differentials within the residen— tial sectors of conterminous United States. From this will flow a comparative analysis of residential differential fer- tility patterns. The point to be emphasized is that the unit of analysis for this study is the "community," which when Operationalized is equivalent to the residential compo- nent of a county. It is to be noted that this approach to the study of fertility is in complete contradistinction to the large-scale, contemporary studies of fertility which 56United Nations, Op. cit., p. 85. 61 claim the individual respondent as their unit of analysis. A partial rationale for our approach is that fertility is largely a social phenomenon and that fertility measures are themselves group measures. Under such an assumption the level of analysis required must be sociological. In sug- gesting the need for comparative studies of "groups of peOple" rather than "person," Bogue asserts that: It would seem that procedures for making comparative studies of groups of peOple must constitute an important part of social science methodology. The fact is that this is a badly neglected aSpect. Present concern is largely with studies designed to analyze data for indi— viduals. Hence, it is essential that techniques for comparative group analysis be devised. This would include not only practicable solutions to the problems of data-handling, but also an ppprOpriate point of view from which to design studies{57 In terms of definition, a community is both a social entity and a territorial entity. Hawley has defined the community as "the structure of relationships through which a localized pOpulation provides its daily requirements."58 In this study community and community structure are to be considered interchangeable. Furthermore, it is assumed that the social environment of the community, or community struc- ture, effects measurable influences on the behavioral pat- terns of the peOple interacting within that community. 57Donald Bogue and D. Harris, Comparative Population and Urban Research via Multiple Regpession and Covariance Analysis (Oxford, Ohio: Scripps Foundation, Miami Univer- sity, 1954), p. l (italics mine). 58Amos Hawley, Human Ecology.(New York: Ronald, 1950), p. 180. 62 In the design of this study the variables employed are to be considered indices of the social structure of the community. To Operationalize the concept of community, however, for the purposes of this study the census definitions of rural-farm, rural—nonfarm, and urban will be accepted. The census classifies the pOpulation of a county on the basis of residence in an urban place or in a rural area. Hence, the "urban community" constitutes all persons living within urban areas as defined by the census within a Specific county. Persons living in the rural area of a county are further classified into rural-farm and rural—nonfarm. Rural residents to be classified as rural—farm must live on a place of 10 acres or more from which the sale of farm prod- ucts amounted to $50 or more in 1959, or on places of less than 10 acres from which sales of farm products amounted to $250 or more in 1959. The rural-nonfarm population of a county, then, is a residual which remains only after the rural—farm and urban pOpulation have been identified.59 Consequently, to accept these definitions is to admit one set of criticisms aimed at the validity of these concepts; but to further equate these definitions to respective 59For a more detailed discussion of the definition of residence categories see U.S. Bureau of the Census, U._S_. Census of ngfllation: 1960. gpneral and Social Economic Characteristics, United States Summary, Final Report PC (1)— 1C (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1962), pp. Vii—viii. 63 "communities" must admit even another set of weaknesses. But, of course, it is difficult to find any Operational definition of "community" without deficiencies. The problem is well stated by Jonassen when he says: Thus the student of communities in modern urban soci- eties is faced with problems of delimitation and over— lapping boundaries of community systems no matter what type of community_unit he chooses to analyze. Recogniz- ing that these problems cannot be completely resolved, the term "community" may be used as a generic term to designate types of social systems whose component parts are spatially contingent.6O The unit of analysis for this study, then, remains the residential part of a county. The Spatial eXpression of this Operationalized definition of community facilitates the application of the distributive approach in this study. The urban-rural differential in fertility has been well-documented, almost to the point of contributional sterility, or at least monotony. Such documentation has lost any utility other than providing a description of the pattern of fertility trends, requiring simply the comparison of fertility levels measured at different points of time. The study of the urban-rural differential fertility, indeed the study of differential fertility in general, is in need of alterations in the conventional design of such studies. In short, the "aggregative" approach needs to be complemented 6OChristen T. Jonassen, "Functional Unities in Eighty-Eight Community Systems," American Sociological Society, XXVI (June, 1961), 400. 64 by studies based on the "distributive" approach. This is not to say that the "distributive" approach is a new approach. Rather, in view of the point of progress of urban- rural differential fertility research, it seems greater con— tributions will be made in future studies if a "distributive" design is employed. The present study employs a "distribu- tive" design with hopes of illustrating this point. The distributive approach is best understood when contrasted with the aggregative approach. Bogue, who is a leading promoter of this approach and has recognized the need to apply it to demographic data, differentiates the two basic approaches in the following manner: The pOpulation of a whole country may be studied in two ways--as the residents of a single area universe or as the residents of a Single area universe or as the resi- dents of a congeries of sub-universes of which each sub- universe has a particular location in space. The first approach, the "aggregative," emphasizes the whole; the second approach, the "distributive," emphasizes the parts. These two approaches are complementary, since each answers a class of questions that the other cannot. 61 It is assumed in the distributive approach, when applied to the present study, that fertility rates vary among the areal subunits chosen. In this case, the subarea units are residential components of counties. The basic unit of analysis, therefore, is areal or Spatial in nature. It may be said, then, that among urban parts of counties in the lDonald Bogue, "POpulation Distribution," in Hauser and Duncan, The Study of ngulation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959), p. 383. 65 United States some are relatively high, others low, and others intermediate. What initially was a Single fertility rate for the nation is now the weighted average of the rates of the subareas, e.g., the urban parts of counties. Bogue labels this "internal diversity" or "place variance."62 If this variation of fertility rates is nonrandom, i.e., per— sistently higher in some areas than in others, there must be ascertainable reasons for this diversity. It is assumed that eXplanation or interpretation of the particular distri- bution of a population event, such as the distribution of fertility levels among the urban, rural-nonfarm, or rural- farm components of counties in the United States, lies in the differential composition and/or the differential environ— mental conditions of the subarea population. EXplanation rather than description should be the objective of the distributive approach, although this has not been the case in many pOpulation distribution studies. Thus, such a study should not be directed toward the question of ppy_variations in fertility occur, but ypy they occur in a sociological sense. To "break through" the descriptive phase Bogue suggests that: The factors that produce given pOpulation events can be ascertained only by a broad comparative analysis, such as observation of the variation of the events and attri- butes in a number of different areas and observation of which characteristics that vary among the areas covary with the pOpulation event. This requires that a hypoth- esis be formulated about what Specific appects of the 62Ibid. 66 environment are related to the_population events. If a given factor varies independently of the pOpulation event (does not covary with it), it may be presupposed not to be an eXplanatory factor for the deviation of the local area from the nation average.63 The present study, therefore, will attempt to devise hypoth— eses to determine why selected compositional and environmen- tal factors should be found to systematically correlate with fertility variation among residential sectors of counties. Thus, the design of the distributive approach is "causal" only in the fact that causes are inferred from a theoretical framework, not from the discovery of a statistical relation- Ship. This statement is a brief discussion of the distribu- tive approach to fertility. Interestingly, Bogue himself has presented an illustrative research program for a dis— tributional analysis of fertility. In this brief illustra- tion he states: It has been demonstrated that much interarea variation persists when age and color composition are controlled, and much work has been devoted to Showing that fertility differentials exist among various occupational, income, religious, social and other groups. But as yet there has been no measure of how much variation in fertility each factor eXplains when all others are controlled or of how much variation remains when all these factors are considered simultaneously. . . . This would call for a multiple-variable distribution analysis of fertility measures for the white and nonwhite pOpulation separate— ly, controlled for age and marital status. 63gb_iél.. p. 390 (italics mine). 64Ibid., p. 398. 67 In a limited sense, the present study attempts to perform this task with the use of multiple regression analysis. The analysis is focused only on the white population of the United States. Age is controlled by the inclusion of age variables as independent variables in the regression equa— tion. Marital status is partially controlled in that the dependent variable, fertility measured as the number of children ever—born per 1,000 ever-married women age 15 to 44, is measured only for the ever~married segment of women of the child-bearing age span. Limitations of the distributive approach are to be noted. First, the character of the subarea boundaries are arbitrary in one sense, but fixed in another sense. They are arbitrary in that there is an infinite variety of ways by which the subareas of a given territory, such as the United States, can be divided. They are fixed in that cen— sus data are collected from predetermined political bound— aries, such as the county, which may not necessarily conform 65 to "natural" boundaries. There are two major schools of 65This limitation is not only inherent in the dis— tributive approach but also pertains to any correlation analysis employing demographic data for spatial units. Hagood and Price allude to this problem as well as four other problems associated with applying correlation analysis to demographic data: unequal size of units, choice of order of demographic unit, tendency for demographic characteristics not to be normally distributed, and lack of independence of observations. Margaret J. Hagood and Daniel 0. Price, Statistics for Sociologists (rev. ed.; New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, 1952), pp. 350-55. 68 thought among distribution analysts represented in the "homogeneous area" vs. the "nodal area" argument. It will be necessary only to distinguish the two schools inasmuch as they relate to this particular problem. The former main— tains that the areal units should be of maximum internal homogeneity; the latter argues for the maximization of rela- tionships and, therefore, that areas are to be delimited on the basis of functional interrelationships. This latter school is represented by metropolitan regionalism and the distance gradient is employed as a major device for studying the internal structure of nodal areas. Bogue calls for a distributional analysis which takes account of both concepts simultaneously.66 The present study at a simplified level could be considered an attempt to include both notions. The influence of metropolitan regions is assumed by the inclu— sion of a measure of ecological distance from metropolitan centers as defined by the census. On the other hand, and without contradiction of the nodal area hypothesis, it is assumed that variation between counties with respect to residential sectors is greater than within counties. But, of course, a county is not necessarily a homogeneous unit, and, therefore, the criterion of maximizing internal homo— geneity is not really carried out. The "nodal area" approach is emphasized by the employment of a metropolitan dominance framework. 66Ibid., pp. 394-5. 69 A second limitation of the distributive approach is the contiguity problem. Briefly, this problem arises from the fact that areal units are not independent of each other but are contiguous. In other words, counties Situated close to each other are more likely to be similar in their charac- teristics than are counties which are some distance apart or grouped together at random.67 However, the problem may be somewhat resolved considering the number of variables employed in the multiple regression analysis. As Bogue states, "the error may be expected to decline as the number of variables considered simultaneously is increased."68 A third limitation of distributional analysis is the ecological correlation problem. Briefly, it is the inability to generalize from findings based on areal units of observa- tion to the individuals contained in those areal units.69 Responses to Robinson's criticisms have tended to reduce the severity of the problem by developing meaningful interpreta- tions of ecological relationships.70 Duncan hints at the 67Otis D. Duncan, Ray P. Cuzzort, and Beverly Duncan, Statistical Geography_(Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press, 1961), p. 129. 68 Donald Bogue, op. cit., p. 397. 69W. S. Robinson, "Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Individuals," American Sociological Review, XV, 1950, 351-57. 70Leo A. Goodman, "Some Alternatives to Ecological Correlation," American Sociological Review, LXIV, 1959, 610-25; Leo A. Goodman, "Ecological Regression and Behavior of Individuals," American Sociolpgical Review, XVIII, 1953, 663-4; L. A. Goodman and W. H. Kruskal, "Measures of 70 potential contribution from a nexus of ecological and socio- logical analysis when he asserts that ". . . areal differen— tials are significant in their own right. There is even sociological basis for supporting that such differentials may reflect factors influencing demographic phenomenon that would not come to light in studying individual characteris— tics solely."7l In a recent study72 Duncan illustrates the effect of ecological factors on fertility over and above the effects of socio-economic variables measured on an individual level. Applying multiple classification analysis to selected vari- ables from the 1941 Indianapolis Household Survey, Duncan determined the net effect of median census tract rent, dwelling—unit rent of the couple, wife's education, hus- band's education, wife's age at marriage, spouses' region of birth, and tenure on fertility. The study concludes that (l) the areal classification of rent levels produces fertil— ity variations which are partially independent ofanuiadditive to those due to the classification of individual dwelling Association for Cross—Classification," Journal of the American Statistical Association, XLIX, 1953, 732—64; and O. D. Duncan and Beverly Davis, "An Alternative to Ecological Correlation," American Sociological Review, XVIII, 1953, 665-66. 71Otis Dudley Duncan, "Human Ecology and Population Studies," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Popula- tion (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959), p. 693. 72Otis Dudley Duncan, "Residential Areas and Differ- ential Fertility," Eggenics Quarterly, XI, June, 1964, 82-89. .0 .4 cu 71 units by rent and that (2) analysis in which an areal clas— sification is examined Simultaneously with Several individ— ual classifications of socio-economic characteristics sug- gest that areal differentials in fertility may not be com- pletely reducible to the areally clustered effects of some conventional individual variables. Hence, the analysis of the effects of ecological variables on fertility behavior is worthy of separate investigation as it contributes to addi- tional understanding of fertility variation. Hashmi, who employed the distributive approach to study fertility variation among census tracts in Chicago, also argues for the significance of ecological correlations in themselves in the following passage: For the present study, the criticisms of Robinson are only partially relevant. It should be remembered that a birth rate is an attribute of a population as a group and is intended to imply nothing about the behav— ior of individual couples within the population. In other words, a birth rate is an average of the behavior of groups having high or low fertility. In fact, it is exactly in this "ecological" sense that birth rates have been interpreted in the past. . . . The study of fer— tility rates within census tracts and a correlation of the social and economic tract characteristics that are associated with them is therefore of interest and funda— mental importance for its own sake. . . . In fact, the total environmental "climate" or socio—economic context within which low or high fertility takes place may be a much more important goal of demographic research than the development of pgobability statements that apply to individual couples. 73Sultan S. Hashmi, "Trends and Factors in Urban Fertility Differences in the United States," op. cit., pp. 196—7. 72 Hashmi further argues that, nevertheless, inferences can be made from ecological correlation to the individual if inter- preted properly and with due caution. A high ecological correlation does suggest that on the average individual couples tend to behave in the direction indicated by the ecological correlation, unless there are specific interven— ing variables operating. However, these unknown intervening variables can be controlled through partial correlation. Hence, by holding constant these disturbing factors, the probability of the conformity of the two levels of correla- tions is increased.74 However it is to be emphasized that the present study will not attempt to "bridge the gap" between these levels of correlation analysis, Since the ecological approach in nexus with the sociological will be quite sufficient to provide the interpretation of variation of fertility levels among residential components of counties. Since this study deals with a group measure as the dependent variable, it must likewise provide its analysis at the same level. To summarize, the basic design of the present study is distributive in character. The variation in fertility that exists among residential sectors of counties in the United States will be explained by variation in selected social environmental or community structural factors. 74Ibid., pp. 197—8. 73 Community and residential component of county are to be con— sidered interchangeable in this study. Since interest lies in why fertility levels fluctuate among communities, hypoth- eses will be constructed concerning expected relationships between community attributes and community fertility levels. Color, age, and marital status will be controlled to some extent. Finally, this study will not stop merely with the intensive study of urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm fertility. The eventual objective is to compare systemati- cally the different fertility patterns of each residential sector. The distributive approach is not new and several distributive studies of fertility within residential groups have been completed.75 However, these studies have tended to be highly descriptive, except for Hughes, Hashmi, and Andarawewa, and limited in scope in terms of the territory 75Some examples of studies employing the distribu— tive approach are E. de S. Brunner and J. H. Kolb, Rural Social Trends (New Yerk: McGraw-Hill, 1933), Ch. V, "Rural and Urban Relationships," pp. 111—19; P. K. Whelpton, "Geo- graphic and Economic Differentials in Fertility," Annals, CLXXXVIII (November, 1936), 37—55; W. S. Thompson and N. E. Jackson, "Fertility in Rural Areas in Relation to Their Distance from Cities, 1930," Rural Sociology, V (June, 1940), 143-62; C. M. Rosenquist and A. H. Schafft, "Differential Fertility in Rural Texas," Rural Sociology, XII (March, 1947), 21—26; 0. D. Duncan, "Fertility of the Village Popula- tion in Pennsylvania, 1940," Social Forces, XXVIII (March, 1950), 304-9; R. B. Hughes, Jr., "Human Fertility Differen— tials: The Influence of Industrial-Urban Development on Birth Rates," Population Review, III (July, 1959), 58—69; S. S. Hashmi, 0p. cit.; and A. Andarawewa, "An Economic Analysis of Fertility Differentials among Rural-Farm Commu- nities in the United States in 1960" (unpublished Ph.D. dis— sertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, 1964). 74 on which the study focuses, except for the Andarawewa study, which is a sister study to the present one and has drawn upon the same data, though it focuses only on the rural-farm sector of the United States. Furthermore, not one of these studies has attempted a comparative analysis of all resi- dence groups based upon the results of a distributive analy- sis. The characteristic of these studies has been to dwell only on one residence group where the distributive approach has been applied. Summary: Requisites of Needed Research on the Urban-Rural Fertilipy Differential In View of how much has been written to this point regarding the nature of the basic problem of this thesis, it might be profitable to recollect the main points of this chapter. The primary purpose of this chapter has been to specify in detail the type of research in differential fer- tility that is needed today. Indications have been scattered throughout the chapter, of course, of the optimistic expecta— tion that this particular study will be able to meet these needs. In a sense, then, one may consider several of the points presented and supported in this chapter as providing the basic requisites of currently needed research on the urban-rural fertility differential. In another sense, how- ever, one could view these requisites as a resumé of the definitive characteristics of the design of the present study. follows: 1. 10. 75 These requisites presented in concise form are as Fertility is the problematic factor in population growth today and therefore requires intensive research. Fertility is primarily social behavior, not attitude. Fertility is a socio-demographic phenomenon in large measure dependent upon the social milieu. The current approach to differential fertility is a causal approach, involving the testing of empiri— cally substantive hypotheses which raise the ques— tion "why?" Fertility is group behavior explanable at the eco- logical or areal level. In spite of predictions of the eventual convergence of urban and rural fertility levels, urban and rural fertility must be studied independently with an eye toward looking inside each type of fertility behav- ior to isolate factors that have a determinative relationship to fertility. The test must be made of the possibility that a different set of factors influence rural fertility viS-a-vis urban fertility or that the same factors have a different effect on rural fertility than on urban fertility. There exists a considerable amount of variation in fertility levels of communities within all residence groups and such variation is explanable by variation of the socio-environmental attributes of communities. Census data can and Should be employed to facilitate the discovery of correlates of residential fertility variation because they lend themselves well to the construction of empirical measures and the applica- tion of statistical techniques of analysis on an interval scale. Multiple regression is employed as a very useful statistical technique which can handle several vari— ables simultaneously, determine the direction and relative importance of the independent variables in explaining fertility variation, and estimate the proportion of the variation in fertility explained by the independent variables. 76 11. The problem of determining correlates of residential fertility variation and the employment of multiple regression analysis are embraced within the broader scope of the distributive approach to fertility analysis as the major design of the present study. The distributive approach is cross—sectional rather than longitudinal. 12. The unit of analysis employed in this study is the residential component of a county, interchangeable with the term "community." 13. Controls are included for color, age, and marital status. 14. Since the study is basically comparative of the correlates of urban and rural fertility variation, there must be an attempt to systematically contrast the results of distributional analysis of the residential categories. Origin and Ogganization of the Study The present study is an outgrowth of a larger study conducted by Dr. J. Allan Beegle, Department of Sociology, and Dr. Dale E. Hathaway, Department of Agricultural Econom— ics, at Michigan State University. The larger study will appear as one of the 1960 Census Monograph series. The data on which the larger study is based, as well as this thesis, are essentially drawn from the 1960 Census of Population statistics on social and economic characteristics of persons enumerated on the basis of a 25 percent sample of the popula- 'tion of the United States. A truncated version of the Cen- saus magnetic tape, from which the Bureau of Census published 77 76 the third its General Social and Economic Characteristics, volume in the PC (1) series, was obtained for use in prepar— ing the monograph by finances granted by the Social Science Research Council. The statistical analyses were carried out by the Armour Research Corporation of the Illinois Institute of Technology in Chicago on a Remington-Rand Univac 1105 Computer. All variables included in this study were also included in the original Census tape with the exception of the metropolitan dominance variable.77 Since in this chapter the nature of the problem of this dissertation has been established and the requisites of a design to study this problem have been posited, a brief description of the organization of what is to follow is now appropriate. Chapter II contains a systematic review of differential fertility studies. First, a broad overview of the range of differential fertility studies is presented followed by an intensive review of a select group of empir— ical studies. A list of criteria is employed to determine the studies out of an innumerable host of differential fer- tility studies which are considered most relevant to the 76U.S. Bureau of the Census, United States Census gfi'Population: 1960 General Social and Economic Characteris- tics, PC (1), 1C (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1962) . 77For details as to how this variable was operation- alized for insertion on the original census tape see pp. 231- 236 of this dissertation. 78 present study. This review attempts to summarize the find- ings of these selected empirical studies in terms of the relationships between fertility behavior and the independent variables. Chapter III establishes metropolitan dominance theory as the theoretical framework by which hypotheses are generated. Urban dominance theory is rejected in favor of metropolitan dominance theory as the more meaningful frame- work by which to investigate urban-rural fertility differen- tial patterns. Chapter IV sets forth the methodological procedures employed to test the theoretical hypotheses derived from metropolitan dominance theory. Both the con— ceptual and statistical frameworks of this study are pre— sented. Chapter V contains the main body of the study, the analysis of fertility data at two territorial levels: national and divisional. Finally, Chapter VI contains some reflections about the findings of the analysis chapter and implications for further research in the area of differen— tial fertility. CHAPTER II REVIEW OF RELEVANT LITERATURE Fertility has been and continues to be a popular Object for empirical study, as the number of fertility studies would attest. The quantity Of such studies renders impossible the task Of a complete review Of the literature dealing with fertility within the space of a single chapter. There are a few excellent sources to which the reader is directed for information concerning a general overview, codification, and/or evaluation of the development Of the study of fertility.1 lCharles Westoff, "The Changing Focus of Differen- tial Fertility Research: The Social Mobility Hypothesis," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXI (January, 1953), 24-5. This article presents a simple, but historically oriented classification Of differential fertility studies up to the Indianapolis Study. Several bibliographic references are cited for each category of his scheme. Bernard Okun, Trends in Birth Rates in the United States Since 1870 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1958), Part III. Okun suggests a six— fold classification Of fertility studies on the basis of methodological approach with illustrations included. United Nations, Department of Social Affairs, The Determinants and Igpnsequences of Population Trends (New York: United Nations, 1953), Ch. V, "Economic and Social Factors Affecting Fertil- ity," pp. 71—97. This source gives a well documented review of factors which have been employed in studies of fertility trends and differentials. The references cited, however, luave a very heavy international flavor. Ronald Freedman, '“The Sociology of Human Fertility: A Trend Report and Bilfliography," Current Sociology, X-XI, No. 2 (1961-62), Sup. 35-119. Freedman offers a very thorough review of the satudy of fertility in the post—war period. The publication 79 80 Two functions of a review of literature of fertility studies are of immediate interest: (1) to assist the researcher in evaluating the contribution of his particular study to the study of fertility in general and (2) to pro— vide a basis for the construction of meaningful propositions with respect to the problem at hand. In the first chapter we have considered the general problem of urban—rural fertil- ity differences. It was established that there is consider- able variation within urban and rural fertility which remains to be explained. Furthermore, it was asserted that a major question to be further investigated is whether fertility differentials within the urban and rural populations reflect different patterns. The Objective of this chapter, then, is includes a 636 item bibliography. In addition, due to the appearance of several large-scale studies Of factors affect— ing fertility beginning with the Indianapolis Study, numer- ous articles have appeared which take the form of either progress reports or evaluations of such studies. See espe— cially David Goldberg, "Some Recent Developments in American Fertility Research," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960), pp. 137-51; and Ronald Freedman, "American Studies of Family Planning and Fertility: A Review of Major Trends and Issues," in Clyde V. Kiser (ed.), Research in Family Planning_(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1962), pp. 211—27. A partial list of additional articles on the large-scale studies includes: C. V. Kiser, "Exploration of Possibilities for New Studies of Factors Affecting Size of Family," Milbank ,Mpmorial Fund Quarterly, XXXI (1953), 436-80; C. V. Kiser and P. K.‘Whe1pton, "Resume of the Indianapolis Study of Scmial and Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility," Pcmulation Studies, VII (1953), 95—110; C. V. Kiser, E. G. jMishler, C. F. Westoff, and R. G. Potter, Jr., "Development of Plans for a Social Psychological Study of the Fertility <3f Two-Child Families," Population Studies, X (July, 1956), ‘43-52: C. V. Kiser, "Methodological Lessons of the 81 to determine whether there is any empirical support for the hypothesis Of contrasting urban—rural fertility differential patterns. By reviewing several carefully selected empirical studies of fertility pertaining to the urban-rural contrast, empirical propositions can be extracted which will either support or reject the general hypothesis of contrasting urban—rural fertility differentials. If these propositions suggest the possibility of contrasting patterns, then we shall not only feel justified to continue the investigation of this problem, but such empirical propositions establiShed by previous research will serve in addition as guidelines by which to consider theoretical frameworks which can increase Indianapolis Fertility Study," Eugenics Quarterly, III (September, 1956), 152—56; C. V. Kiser and P. K. Whelpton, "Social and Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility: XXXIII. Summary of Chief Findings and Implications for Future Studies," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXVI (July, 1958), 282-329; C. V. Kiser, W. H. Grabill, and J. Schacter, "Plans for the APHA Monograph on Fertility in the 1960 Census Period," in.Emerging Techniques in Population Research (New York: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1963), pp. 82- 101; Milbank Memorial Fund, Current Research in Human Fertil— _i£y (New York: Milbank, 1955); Milbank Memorial Fund, Thirtprears of Research in Human Fertility: Retrospect and Prospect (New York: Milbank, 1959); P. K. Whelpton, "Fertil- ity and Fecundity," in Needed Popplation Research (Lancaster: The Science Press Printing Company, 1938), pp. 40—62; P. K. Whelpton and R. Freedman, "A Study of the Growth of American Families," American Journal of Sociology, LXI (May, 1956), 595-601; C. F. Westoff, E. G. Mishler, R. G. Potter, Jr., and C. V. Kiser, "A New Study of American Fertility, Social and Psychological Factors," Eugpnics Quarterly, II (December, 1955), 229-337 C. F. Westoff, R. G. Potter, Jr., and P. C. Sagi, "Some Selected Findings of the Princeton Fertility Study: 1963," Demography, I (1964), 130—35; and George F. Mair (ed.), Studies in Popglation (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1949), especially Section V, "Future Course of Research in Fertility," pp. 143—69. 82 the depth of analysis of rural-urban differential fertility patterns. Criteria Employed to Select Empirical Studies for Intensive Review Not all fertility studies of an empirical nature bear on the particular problem considered in this thesis. Since the more parsimonious procedure would be to review only those studies which have immediate bearing upon the problem, I adopted Six specific criteria by which to deter— mine the relevancy of any given study to my problem. I decided that in the process of reviewing fertility studies, if a study failed to meet any one of the six criteria, it was to be omitted from further consideration. The six cri- teria which were adopted are: l. The study must be empirical in nature, i.e., must attempt to describe, establish, or explain the existence, direction, degree, and/or nature of the relationship of some independent variables with fer- tility behavior. In other words, it must attempt to explain fertility differences with reference to selected independent variables. 2. The study must use a measure Of fertility as the dependent variable(s). Studies which focus only on such measures as "expected fertility," "fertility planning," "desired size of family," etc., will not be included. Interest lies only in fertility behav— ipp, not attitudes, values, aspiration, or expecta— tions related to fertility. Studies which combine these two aspects of fertility in their general focus may be reviewed. 3. The study must employ at least one of the following variables as the major independent (explanatory, causal, etc.) variable: occupation, female employ- ment, education, income (family, female, etc.), age of women, ecological distance. 83 4. The study must employ data obtained for some areal segment(s), or at least representative of that areal segment, e.g., residence, region, areal sample, cen— sus tract, etc., and/or the entire population of the conterminous United States. 5. The study should add or contribute information re— garding differences between rural and urban fertil- ity levels. 6. The study must focus on primarily white fertility or total fertility where it can be assumed that the white population is a major component of the total population or sample. The intention Of the first criterion was to insure that the design of studies to be reviewed were comparable to that of the present study. It omitted articles dealing with the phenomenon of fertility which were not empirical. The first criterion also eliminated studies which employed fer— tility as an independent variable, or studies which dealt only with the major processes of population change, i.e., studies in formal demography, but which failed to relate any extraneous variables to these processes. The second criterion tended to eliminate from con— sideration studies that did not treat fertility behavior as a dependent variable. Since the appearance of the Indianap— olis Study there has appeared a new "twist" to fertility studies: the investigation of "family planning," desired family size," and the like, as the key to understanding .fi- ..- 84 differential fertility.2 These studies often employ fertil- ity attitudes rather than fertility behavior as their depen— dent variable. These studies have been eliminated from review since the factors which affect attitudes toward fer- tility planning are not necessarily the same as those affecting actual fertility. The third criterion was most effective in reducing the number of studies for review. The present study in— cludes six general categories of explanatory variables to be related with fertility behavior. These categories, of course, were determined largely by the availability of types of census data included in the census tape. Nevertheless, the variables selected for analysis had been employed 2A partial list Of studies employing dependent vari— able of fertility attitudes, such as, "desired family Size," "family planning," etc.: C. F. Westoff, E. G. Mishler, and E. L. Kelly, "Preferences in Size of Family and Eventual Fertility Twenty Years After," American Journal of Sociology, LXII (March, 1957), 491—97; C. F. Westoff, P. C. Sagi, and E. L. Kelly, "Fertility Through Twenty Years of Marriage; A Study in Predictive Possibilities," American Sociological Review, XXIII (October, 1958), 549-56: R. Freedman, P. K. Whelpton, and A. A. Campbell, Family Planning, Sterility and _Pppulation Growth (New YOrk: McGraw-Hill, 1959); C. A. Yeracaris, "Differentials in the Relationship between Values and Practices in Fertility," Social Forces, XXXVIII (December, 1959), 153-58; C. F. Westoff, R. G. Potter, Jr., P. C. Sagi, and E. G. Mishler, Family Growth in Metrppolitan America (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1961); C. F. Westoff, R. G. Potter, Jr., and P. C. Sagi, The Third Child: A Study in Prediction of Fertility (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963); D. Goldberg, H. Sharp, and R. Freedman, "The Stability and Reliability of EXpected Family Size Data," Milbank Memorial Fund_guarterly, XXXVII (October, 1959), 369—85; and Jeanne Ridley, "Number of Children Expected in Relation to Non-Familial Activities of the Wife," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXVII (July, 1959), 277-96. 85 traditionally in other fertility studies. In spite of this several fertility studies still failed to meet this crite— rion. For such studies not even one of the six classes of variables employed in the present study was also employed in that investigation.3 3A partial list of studies omitted from review because of failure to meet the third criterion: D. G. Marshall, "The Decline in Farm Family Fertility and Its Relationship to Nationality and Religious Background," Rural Sociology. XV (March, 1950), 42-49; R. Freedman, P. K. Whelpton, and J. W. Smit, "Socio-Economic Factors in Reli— gious Differentials in Fertility," American Sociological Review, XXVI (August, 1961), 608—14; Erich Rosenthal, "Jewish Fertility in the United States," Eugenics Quarterly, VIII (December, 1961), 198—217; H. E. Brooks and F. J. Henry, "An Empirical Study of the Relationships of Catholic Prac— tice and Occupational Mobility to Fertility,“ Milbank Memo- rial Fund Quarterly, XXXVI (July, 1958), 222-81; P. C. Glick, "Inter-Marriage and Fertility Patterns among Persons in Major Religious Groups," Eugenics Quarterly, VII (March, 1960), 31—38; W. S. Thompson, "Differentials in Fertility and Levels of Living in the Rural Population of the U. S.," American Sociolpgical Review, XIII (October, 1948), 516-34; Margaret Hagood, "Changing Fertility Differentials among Farm-Operator Families in Relation to Economic Size of Farm," Rural Sociology. XIII (December, 1948), 363—73; E. M. Kita- gawa, "Differential Fertility in Chicago, 1920—1940," American Journal of Sociology, LVIII (March, 1953), 481—92; A. J. Mayer and C. Klapprodt, "Fertility Differentials in Detroit: 1920—50," Population Studies, IX (November, 1955), 148—58; E. G. Flittie, "Fertility and Mortality in the Rocky Mountain West," American Sociolpgical Review, XXII (April, 1957), 189-937 H. Y. T'ien, "A Demographic Aspect of Inter- state Variations in American Fertility, 1800-1860," Milbank Memorial Fundlgparterly, XXXVII (January, 1959), 49—59; W. Bash, "Changing Birth Rates in Developing America: New York State, 1840-1875," Milbank Memorial Fund Qpprterly, XLI (April, 1963), 161-82; and Sidney Goldstein and Kurt Mayer, "Residence and Status Differences in Fertility," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XLIII (July, 1965), 291-310. 86 Since the design of the present study calls for the study of fertility differentials on an areal distribution basis, it was necessary for comparability that studies to be reviewed be based on or represent some areal segment(s) Of the United States (Criterion 4). Thus, fertility studies based on samples which were representative of some distin- guishable territory or areal unit, such as, a region, a city, a group Of cities, etc., were acceptable. The fourth crite- rion tended to eliminate two types of studies: those based on data from survey samples which were not areal samples4 and those based on data collected from populations outside conterminous United States.5 4A partial list Of studies based on non—areal sam- ples or populations: R. Gutman and I. Bender, "Some Sources of Variation in Family Size of College Graduates," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXV (July, 1957), 287-301: C. F. Westoff, P. C. Sagi, and E. L. Kelly, "Fertility through Twenty Years of Marriage: A Study in Predictive Possibil— ities," American Sociological Review, XXIII (October, 1958), 549—56; P. Lauriat, "Marriage and Fertility Patterns of College Graduates," Eugenics Quarterly, VI (September, 1959), 171-79; G. S. Becker, "An Economic Analysis of Fertility," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and Economic Change in Developpd Countries (Princeton: Prince— ton UniVersity Press, 1960), pp. 209-31; B. Pasamanick, S. Dinitz, and H. Knoblock, "Socio—Economic and Seasonal Vari- ation in Birth Rates,“ Milbank Memorial Fundpguarterly, XXXVIII (July, 1960), 248-54; and E. D. Baltzell, "Social MObility and Fertility within an Elite Group," Milbank Memo- lglal Fund_guarterly, XXXI (October, 1953), 412—20. 5A partial list of studies based on populations out— side conterminous United States: N. Keyfitz, "Differential Fertility in Ontario: Application of Factorial Design to Demographic Problem," population Studies, VI (November, 1952), 123-34; J. Berent, "Relationship between Family Sizes of Two Successive Generations," Milbank Memorial Fund Qparterl , XXXI (January, 1953), 39—50; N. Keyfitz, "A Factorial 87 The fifth criterion was included to assure that the studies to be reviewed would provide at least some informa- tion on why urban and rural fertility levels differ, i.e., what in the community social structure of these residence groups produces differences in the level of fertility. Very few studies failed to meet this requirement since many studies make accidental or implicit recognition of residence in their designs and analyses. In a majority of cases the decision was arbitrary as to a study's contribution in this respect. Moreover, many studies have tended to focus on urban fertility, Since, according to the transitional theory Arrangement of Comparisons of Family Size," American Journal Of Sociology, LVIII (March, 1953), 470-80; R. McGinniS, "Similarity of Background Characteristics and Differential Fertility," Social Forces, XXXIV (October, 1955), 67-72: D. Wrong, "Trends in Class Fertility in Western Nations," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, XXIV (May, 1958), 216—29; H. Y. T'ien, "The Social Mobility Fer- tility Hypothesis Reconsidered: An Empirical Study," American Sociological Review, XXVI (April, 1961), 247—57; I. Adelman, "An Econometric Analysis of Population Growth," American Economic Review, LIII (June, 1963), 314—339; H. Gille, "An International Survey of Recent Fertility Trends," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Dempgraphic and Economic Change in Developed Countries (Princeton: Prince- ton University Press, 1960), pp. 17—34; R. Hill, J. M. Stycos and K. W. Back, The Family and Population Control (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1959); J. M. Stycos, Family and Fertility in Puerto Rico (New YOrk: Columbia University Press, 1955); Paul Hatt, Backgrounds of Human Fertility in Puerto Rico (Princeton: Princeton Univer— sity Press, 1952); W. Stys, "The Influence of Economic Condi— tions on the Fertility of Peasant Women," gppulation Studies, XI (November, 1957), 136—48; D. Wrong, "Class Fertility Dif- ferentials in England and Wales," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXVIII (January, 1960), 37-47: and David M. Heer and Elsa Turner, "Areal Difference in Latin American Fertil- ity," Population Studies, XVIII (March, 1965), 279-82. 88 of fertility, urban fertility is the level and pattern to- ward which the fertility levels in the high fertility rural areas are moving. Thus, interest in fertility research has been directed mostly toward urban fertility, especially with respect to fertility planning among urban couples, rather than rural fertility.6 Finally, the sixth criterion eliminated from consid- eration studies dealing with nonwhite fertility.7 In the case of studies contrasting white and nonwhite fertility, if they met all the previous criteria, only the white data were considered in the review. 6For example, the following large-scale studies of urban fertility: R. Freedman, P. K. Whelpton, and A. A. Campbell, Family Planning, Sterility and Pppulation Changg (New YOrk: McGraw-Hill, 1959); D. F. Westoff, R. G. Potter, Jr., P. C. Sagi, and E. G. Mishler, Familinrowth in Metro- politan America (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1961; C. V. KiSer, Group Differences in Urban Fertilipy (Baltimore: Williams and Wilkins, 1952); and C. Kiser and P. Whelpton, Social and Ppychological Factors Affecting Fertility (New York: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1943-1954). 7J. E. Dodson, "The Differential Fertility of the Negro Population, Houston, Texas, 1940—1950," Milbank Memo- rial Fund_guarterly, XXXV (July, 1957), 266-79; C. V. Kiser, "Fertility Trends and Differentials among Nonwhites in the United States," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXVI (April, 1958), 149-97; A. Lee and E. Lee, "The Future Fer— tility of the American Negro," Social Forces, XXXVII (March, 1959), 228-31; E. Lee and A. Lee, "The Differential Fertil— ity of the American Negro," American Sociological Review, XVII (August, 1952), 437—47; and J. S. Vandiver, "The Repro— duction Pattern of the Rural Negroes of the Yazoo-Mississippi Delta," Social Forces, XXIX (October, 1950), 78-84. 89 Intensive Review of Selected List of Empirical Studies It is the Objective of this intensive review Of empirical studies selected on the basis Of the Six criteria listed above to facilitate the construction of propositions relevant to our problem. Following an extensive survey of the literature dealing with fertility by which a sizeable bibliography was compiled, thirty-one empirical studies were selected upon the application of our criteria. These studies were thereupon submitted to a battery of questions by which Specific characteristics and basic findings were abstracted from the body of the study. The format of this schedule is exhibited in Appendix B. Considering the now manageable number Of studies to be reviewed, it was possible to transfer this information from the schedule to a summary table as presented in Tables 13 and 14. The intensive review requires three stages. First, some general statements are made to indicate the range in characteristics Of these selected studies. Second, consid- eration is granted to the designs of these studies as they compare with the design of this fertility study as proposed in the previous chapter. Finally, an attempt is made to summarize the findings of these 31 studies inasmuch as they are relevant to this particular study of fertility. 9() .312: .803 .056. > .Nfifiuom Hahn-l :5an .mowuuo loam 08000.3 HHS—n. Ou sawumaox 5.. 0002 Hanna 5 hawuwuumb; 5003006 .m .2 can comma-03a. .m .Bu .wmlou gonad £0305 HHHBOOBU .3052 ...»uzmvuom 5 000:0.uouuwc 0030.. .fiou0ouoz .3 .mo .97: .....n3 $000055 35.830 .3005 2.333000 5 083500003 33:30 05 62058000.. 63306. .s .00 ..IIIIIIIIII .34: .00 .0030 ...-30300 0300 0:0 ~38... .> :8 £83 Juan—130009. 3.qu 30.: 0000.2. 13000 102. .58. .m .6 0:0 005500 .0 00 .00 .0963 .133 40005 x .Nauouuama veal. Hum: gal 0.93.33 gun :0 3 095.00 game—50o 0.3.333 no auuawuuonm 08,—... .gdnmm .x can floanouon .8 .mn .210 .233 £305 29 030300000 Hmuaunaunum 003.0! 0.3 an HEB—8b 0.0030 300% 00 5.3004 haundmuuom Hauusouuuuwca 5.3000002 .3 3:00.“ can u0¥0wuu§mm .m 003mm 03.30 0000." 00.3.3 0» id gum 804 2%....- HH 95000 .095 03030.0 mucus—006 use 00.— m in! 320 A55: H0 000M... 50000 on 5 Hanna one." 000000 came 0009005. .0 g 0.3% 035 one mung JUNE—Hal 00895 DOE-Mm IE- .Eu) 8.." Hum EU lanes 03.30 0095.3: c 0095 cmma h0g0 madman HE 0mm." 050000002 .m 00.3w". 00000.30 $1.3 00!: out.) 084 0500 now «use 0083 0:0 Hum m Henna 00.6.3.5 15090.3 nowuwu cuoauuoc c 008.5 omma 150 came n053.00 omen 6000.305. .4» £5. 0 be .000 80; 003560 00 won a 3g 0006.350 0030 oceansouuae "0000 4.55 00300000 030 88.9... 520 883 «mvlcu 5'0! Hon cu H095 25006 000A m hi8 .0330 ha a a 3mm: 053— 095.36 «300..— humflgah I953 004015.303 ca smash one." 000000 nmmd was Mean—:3 .m passion-:0 00:0 lush Ben—.7259: .ouud coc.ccm 00.300! No 0.000% ccc ..n 0350a 00 cocoon no 090000 cam." loam gaaum won on 000:0 a! 0» nuu 100.00: 00.330 000.3000 mm 0095 cam." 800.8 300.00 one." use s 0000002 .~ .000 2. “Honda ous—3300 .3000! 0000 saunas—mom 02.6.3 .00an 30.00093 0350: no 02300 00 08.03 00430 A02 000000 0.8." Baum 050000002 can sum—.00 .0035 con son a I952 0.03308 mm .0085 000 008.5 3S .5000 0.3-3m on: noxguuaocam ..— 000008. 333000 0300.0 0000000003 .0 .0 00305300 0300.200 008 ....o 03:00 0303 . 309304 «0 000.000 «00.: 95.5 0900 IA?— 033000 0000:0000 0000300.. “0.000% 000» IIIIIIIII'IIIII'IIIIIIIIIIFI‘IF .3000 030035 000 0000300 03050 333—00 00 033 in .fl 032. 9]. .muqom ..omma .00002. HHH>xx .uouuom Hmfloom =.oema .000000000000 00 0000000000 ommaaw> 0:0 no 000000000: .000000 000000 mauoo .¢¢~ImmH .Amema .kumav HH>XX sNHu0uum0o 000m HawHOBoz xcmnawz =.m0umum DMEO:OOMI0w00m ha moumm mu“ Infiuuuh 000 mcwncmam auwawuu0m .xH "auwaauu0m mcwuu0wm< muouumm Hmowm0H0n0>0m 000 a0w00m: .noumaon3 .x .0 0:0 “onfix .> .00 .omnaw .Ahema .noumz. HHx .Nmmmmwmom wmuam ..mmxoa 00090 :0 000000000 000000000000: .0000000 .0 00>H< 000 0000000000 .2 00000 .omlamn .Amema .xa0nv Hxx .Hw000000o 000k amuuoamz xcmnaaz =.0«H0Q000«00H :« 00Hm000 0uaazl0>wumz mm0.a¢ maoad anaeauu0m H0000000MMflo .H “hudafiuu0h mcwuuomu< muouomm HmoamOHonohmm 000 Hmaoom: .000Hx .> .U 000 Goumdunz .& .mn .an¢ma .mawxawz 000 memfiaaws "ouOEMuamm. waaauu0m 00805 0% 00000H0uwwo m0ouw .uonwx .> owhnUm Aoumum «0 .000 .aaw> m\Hv welma 00803 ooo.a 0>wu0 .0000 :w .mom oom.m Eumucoz 000 m 00000 :0ucauzo Inauumwo H0000 m0mmaaw> oeo Iamu0m o¢mH 000000 omad 000000o .HH .0000 .000 unflauum .0H«H 0000000 0005 >000 0000A 0w 0000000 .00000000 00 00 00000 .800: .o« H0000 ouw3 .00300000 .mmlnnmu 0000005 ..0000 .0uwa3l0>wuac 0>uumm . 0H030m h00um 000AH0£3 .00Hn000 cad 00m :00 noumm< mdaommcmwucu 0000: Head mdaommcmwwcH 000a wan u0udx .OH 0>wu0 ecuma 00303 ooo.H Inwuuuao 00x09 oumwasum 0:0 000 m 000:0 coucmwnu 0 no 00000000 0mm Eummnamu0m cema 000000 h0ma 0000000000 .0 m0 A , H0000 0ww3 .vowuumalouao m .00033100w000 .00000000 0>w00 _ %0>H0m 0H0£000om nu0nux .vvnma 00003 ooa 000 0M0 Inauuuwn waaommqawqu cmnuo Hews awaoamcuacau m¢md 000 noumaoaz .0 000000 m :w .000 m~ 00000000 "H0000 «.m.D 00000 0H0500 .mmmn 000% you vfilma 00>«3 0>wumm no .000000 000000 H0000 Hanan a0>H0m ooo.~ 00A onuuan obaq Ioummd ma 0“ 00%»«0 mm 00am .00009 mmon cannon H000dumz N¢mH uuouwx .5 000000: hudaduuoh amw000 0000000000m .m .D conunmnnlfi 00000HAOU 0000 no 00000» voznad Auvuonu0< m0 aunoauom H0000 @0000 0000 In0m ounnwun> 0000:0000 , 00000u00¢ 609000» H00» moscwucouuunu 00000 S92 .m~¢lmmn .Ammwa .quOuoov Huxxx .Nauuuumna‘unam Hmwuoauz stand“: 3.0mmauceoa mcuuac asumum uwaocoomIOMUOm ha huaawuuoh cw momcmnus .uoawx .> .oo .mmuaoa .Ammma .awum0m AmowmmaowOOm cmuwuoad =.NmmH ou oooa unmumum Guyana 0:» ca %uwawnuuh Hmwucwumuuung .uwouuo3 .m uoaumnoo .nmlmhd .Ammmd .Haummv Hbe .3U«>om HaofimoHofiuom nwuauaafl :.uoumum mouficb on» ad auwawuuum can noduamnuoo- .Hoxcfin .2 uuunbmn an‘ .mmuaoa .Awmma .auunxv HH>ux .GOHumauound anuauuwuwum nmoauofid 0:» no Managed =.m0umum umuwcs ozu cw mamwucwuomuflo can uvcmus huwaauuomg .kuux .> .om onH a»« melma c0803 ouusz 0>wumm mm can o¢ma Iawuuom no .Afim . cofiuumauuu>o ooo.H you man uoumo¢ moumum conga: .mza .cmnua omma Hmaoomm "anacou mmma ououax .oa ouas3lo>fiumc .mmsuoo .00 0mm Cu cauuvumocmum 0>wuma . .uwm cw ~\H u0>o =c36u: usmcmo .nobw3 ooa uom mmo loumm4 .xucaoo cowaomz can amusm mama oumum xupw 30a mama . Gamma .mH meuma c0803 ooo.a Mom m uooc: convawcu ".oaom “wouuameoo. +m¢ .A.uuao. o¢uoom~ maunoo ¢vlma :0503 ooo.a awn m>wumm hfima “>m>unw m noon: coucawso “@5000 louvma mwumum oouaco amusulcmnua Nmma .mom ucmuuno «mad unwoumoz .¢H ucumoum unanuan .oco vawuume .ouag3lo>wumc o>wumm Gama molow :0303 ooo.H uvm mmo noumma .m.D «0 mcowmou w Hmunulnmnub 0¢¢H asmcoo «mmn \mwuxcun .ma mmlow :08 cahonEo ooo.H uom Hmuau m nova: nouvaunu «@5000 uow :ofiumo o¢¢a unncmo meumd :oeo: magnuma ooo.a o>aumm ufiamaw 050» head can .nmmd >o>num mom m uucca cuuoawno Ioummc .m.D Hmuoa ".m.D Hauoa ¢vma .mom unouuso «nod vacuum .NH ousnmat audaauuom cognac voucommumom .m .D couanmsmam vououaaoo mama uo cannon conuud Aavuosusd uo mucoemom gamut aaouu mama lash cannuun> unaccomon oucocanom Auvummw F.uuma J; coscaucoollna manna 533 .mn =~umsouo o aocoom can amfloom uaououuwa a“ exam maaanm. .xH .go ..mmaa .Haum -3980: 3:8» 33: 5396 833: om can 322% 5:52 25m .2388 .4 .4 EB 53325 .x .m .55..on 333m. .emnuomu .mm .Ammmn .uuoum ovum any .oouacau. nouaum eunuch on» no coduau 0m «:9 .oamom .b nausea aw 3.:o«umHsmom aounum vouwcb 059 no huaauuu0h ugh: .Hduanuu .m nonduzu Ammmu .aoawt uxuow 3oz. :0203 snowuua< no Nuwawuuoh och .coumaosz .x .m can .uouwx .> .0 .Hdwnuuo .m couawsn IIIIIIIIIIIII: .mhlws ..mmma .uonbuuov >Hxxx .aoouom Amwuom =.ommauo~ma .owcm>amw::um .csbuwwuuoz cw auaawuuom no nauouuum mcamcmnu: .auouucuou hoaowmn wagonnaau anfiuv mmma ha o>wumm “mamamn >o>u=u a coumdosx unuuan no nonlsa omuu0>< loummc .Aonm .mvuv .m.D Buuuacunub mmma admin: ~40 mama .anflcuouh .o~ can ooo.a mom m noon: nouuddsu :30 «NmmH oloucn cusp) ooo.a Hum m anon: caucaanu n30 umvmu maoucu .mvlmv coin: ooo.a Mom mmma ho>usm muo ..uacu .ewlma nob“: o>wumm meme .mom acouuao ooo.a non nun «.mauoo uoummt nmumum cuuflcb Hausuncanua cmma cannon mmmu unawnmuo .ma 213 can gulp: oa souuaano cauuu "oaoucu flush ”couaounccaun muo a “sea a» souuawno Ouumu ”Hmmn .uca .uauuuni .mvuma moan: ooo.u hon m nova: coucaaso «mvma oaou m¢ma law “.uoum .nnsn .coauuae «mma >o>u=m ouno ..ocaun .ouwg: ‘mvumu oamu .acm uaouuao groumaugz cosy: ooo- non mun ".m.q o>gunm ma can cum” on» gun“: nu scab: a ..uauu ..maouo uoumm< noumum oouwcb .mzm .canup ommu uuucoo mama .Huunmuo .ma omma .o¢m~ .onma .onma .uua cannuo woodwon .uh n a“ vegan on: 0&3 cusp: ou abuunm .oanzm no nmsou anon nouuuwso .oc omnuo>4 Ioummd than .czounauuoz sank: omucuma menace: nuuwn mnmn acaouQOAoo .ha ous-cox huuaauuom amwuon . coucoooumom .m .D coma-asmafl vouuonaoo «van no woman» con-«A Auvuonuud no nuaaamom anou¢ nacho auon lava cannuua> ucooconoo oucacunom Anvuonh an.» fllllllrlll UGQGdUBOOIInH OHAGH 94 ..ooma .oowunma .nm .Aooma .muascmn. HHH>xxx . auouu .muoum haamuo>anb aououcaum .mmlawa =.nmumum nouacb ecu mo acaumaamom Bummlcoz msocomavca Gnu new mamaucmuuwuao huaaauuumg .Aaoma m .umAEo>ozv >x .moaoaum acaumaamdm .uomaamoam .9 van amacooum camcom .wmlmw ouch amauOEaz xcmnaaz =.mumo huaaauuum maaommcmavca 0:» an xboq yonuocdg .muunvaou va>mav mo smouam amcoaumz :a :.mumo mamcou mmumum omuaca on» Ca huaaauuwh amaucouuwuan: .moammam mucmz can muammnm wuunoamv .maalhh .mm .aooma .mmmum huamuu>acb Gouwucaum can oasmmummeua .suumonom uaaocoom mo smwusm anneaumz ca =.muumum cuuacb on» Ca kuaaauumm amauaououwana .uonwx .> .00 =.uoumm Suuam no unnamoao>on cmnuDIaMauuuavna mo oocmsawca one unamaunouuumaa muaaauuom unsung .molmm ..mmma .ha9b. HHH .3ba>om ceauaaa om ..uh .uonmnm .m wanna A .mmlvan .ammma .noumzv Hax .moavaum coaumas om :.wouacmnub coaumuucoulo39 mo huaaauuom one: .muonvaow ua>mom “couoocaumv mwauucaou 00m0a0>oo :a ummvno oaaonoum can uasmmummmun .nuumonom uaeocoum "cououaaumv noauuasoo vom0a0>oo ca ummmru uaacaoom ammo. m2 .mmlma .voauuME .0uas3 .umn uo>w was ova; o>auum nucmumafi .m.D now mamamm uvmcauoam .unuuan mo koala: omauo>4 Ioummd nmumuw wouacb Bumuucmnub mmma ho>uam maua sham u> nova magnum auaum Iaanu mo Honla: omnuu>4 Inauuuan maaommamavca tawny: .com N a¢ma maaomwcmavca coma omuonuaoo .mN uaoaoum cannuan .uuco voauuufl .mbauac .aunua obaumm manna .wmuaum «amine amao .onucfi soap) ooo.a you mun Ioummd amuuaoo nuuoz sank: oema Iona nonnamu owma uaoammam .vm ecuma coco: ooo.a yam «mma mo>usm mun "mopusm “mvuma gnu, hmma .mom unouuao 23 21.3 333 8o; mom «>38 mm 33 m anon: couvaanu “cancoo Ioummd nouuum omuasb .mzm .cmnnb omma nancou owma uuooax .mm aa>aav anon Hobo noun luau Iaasu «ho>usm um¢lma :0303 aha»: a.oo :aouaaa «mob Ianuau can amma oamflnm “on mac nouvaaso «nancoo Inauunan luau. oonuoccoa .mom aauoa emma hofihsm aauaou mmma {wwwamnu .NN ucoaoun unanua: A.umal uaouuoa ice ova: :33 ~95 :85 gauum vacuuoo luau w> .385 .950: no can Iaano no Honlnfi omnugt Ioummfi amuaaomouuut .souluv 58.5 mmlumma ulna .893 no: mmma mahogaou .a~ ous-ual huaaauMOh nuance unaccounted .m .D wouannznau vouuaaaoo dune no cannon uanuaa anuubnufld no nunulmom anon: macho anon Invm canuaunb unaccomoo ouauoauom anyway» vosaduBOOIIMH Danna uni” €35 .amoma .uwnfiw>ozv aa>xx .NaaEMh ofiu can UNMauumz no annuaob a.>uaaauumm new «Hausa Mo ceaumamm .oml¢a¢ .hmoma .GGShV HHHA .3oa>0m oaeocoom :muauuafl =.>uaaauuom ou maumum oaaocoum mo coaumamm 0:9: .Gmavomum nmuonoo .mmumv .Avwma .mmlmm .mVIowm .amomav Ha .Nnmmummsoo :.>uaaauuwm amaucmumwmaa can ccdoumxumm Sham: .nmucan .n mauo .ma .A¢oma .mmmum ommoano mo >uamu0>aab .mmoum ommuaso mo huamuu>acb nommuanuv macaoaoom cmnub mmwmusm .m :a =.ommuanollmaaomouuuz 5 Ga auaamuuoz can auaaauuom amaunoummuao ca mvawuag .malmOm «:9: .u::& .m maaaacmo c .uomfimm .2 mnu ca moocmumuuao auaaauuwm :mnub ca muouomm: COamuo> evocaunm omam mwm .coaumuummmao .Q.£m nonmaanamcsv :moumum wouacb onu Ca moucmumuuao huaaauuwm cmnub Ca muouomm new mvwouaa .Hfinmmm .m :muaamm .amoma A on mnoauanauucou .onmom .G can .m can m3mmmuax .2 .mo "ommuanov NmOaOaUOm cmnuD ou macauanauucoo .msmom .a can mmmmusm .m ca =.muumum cwuacb .ommuano mo >uamu¢>acb .amOaanom no ucoauummon Axuaaauuou ta mwumameouv ucmmoum ocmn M Ina: £ua3 .muco umauume .¢¢Imm moon .coEo3 muaLS 0>au mwumum omuaCD mmmum . amamfimm amcoau uwm anon uo>m cmuoaano Immoummd mo mmmu< omuacmnub nwuacmnub ooma m Inc may mamcoo mwma oucsx .am .muaaauuou omuoam _ IEOOV awlm¢ 0mm .0wa3 o>aus ..xomm Gummy m A.m500 ooo.mv ho> non anon um>m :muoaaco unauumaa mmumum couacb Eummlaummcoz Noma WIWuSm .mom ucmuufiu moma mcmunzn .0m a oumocmum .eelma c0203 _ caauumEIua>u ooo.a uwm mnuuan "oumu .OOauumE uv¢lma c0803 ooo.a umm m>aumm ouomnmm new msuuam noun» .uuuw amuoa noumm< ommoaso :mQuD omlomma mumc uomuu msmcmo «oma memmuax .mm Annoy mmma m>au an unuuan wbaa uo umnssz Ianauuman muumum vmuaca swan: mmma oamamm >m>usm mau " Guam: omwuano Mom canauumucmunlommauumz Isnauumaa mmu< .ouuuz omwoaso :mnuD omma p wumc uumuu unncou Noma Mancunm .hN unsmmoz huaaauuom :mauoo coucamoumom .m .D vmnammnmEm umuomaaoofl‘ name no ooufiom conuaa anvuonunfl mo nucufimmm amwu< macho mama . Inflm mannaum> unaccomon mucooanom amvummw H Mama coacaucoouuma manna 96 General Characteristics of Studies It is to be emphasized that the purpose of the elim— ination of studies from review was to focus concern upon studies most relevant to our problem. In spite of the reduction of studies, there remains a considerable range in certain characteristics of these studies. For example, pub— lication dates range from 1930 to 1965 with some tendency to be proportionately more in the post-war period. It is felt that the more current studies based on contemporary data are more relevant to the present study based on 1960 census date. The range of the periods in which data were collected is perhaps of more importance than publication date. Eight studies are based on data collected before 1940, nine in the period 1940-49, eight within the 1950-54 period, four during 1955-59, and only two based on data collected since 1960. There are, of course, other studies of fertility based on data collected since 1960, but most of these have not met the criteria requirements of this review. If nothing more such information suggests the need for a more "up—to—date" differential fertility study based on the 1960 census. With respect to variations in the source of data, of the thirty-one selected studies, 21 are analyses of data pro— vided by census. However, three studies (Table 13:1,2,24) employed census data obtained from special samples. Six studies analyzed data from the intercensal Current Popula- tion Surveys (Table 13:12,l4,18,l9,23,30). Of the ten inves— tigations not based on census data, nine are specially 97 conducted sample surveys (Table l3:5,7,8,10,20,21,25,26,28) and one is based on collected birth records (Table 13:17). Since the present study is also an analysis of census data, it is favorable that a majority of the review investigations are census analyses. Because of the nature of the sources of data avail- able for differential fertility analysis, several overlap— pings occur in terms of the data employed. Two studies (Table 13:1,2) are based on the same special sample obtained from the 1910 census. The Indianapolis Study contributes three studies in this review (Table l3:8,lO,25). Several studies analyzed data from the special census publications of 1940 and 1950 dealing with differential fertility (Table 13:12,13,l4,l6,18,19,23,24). The appearance of the results of the Current Population Surveys 1947, 1949, 1952, 1957 and 1962, contributed to a number of analyses (Table 13:12,14,18, 19,23,30). Three studies were outcomes of the Growth of American Families Study of 1955 (Table 13:20,26,28) and two analyses employed Chicago census tract data of 1950 (Table 13: 27,29). In spite of such "overlappings" studies based on the same source of data tended to vary with respect to the aspects of the data emphasized as well as other characteris- tics of the study. For example, there is a wide range of difference as to the areal segment of the United States rep— resented by the data analyzed. The two most common areal unites in fertility analysis, however, are the national level and a city or metropolitan area level. .....— 98 Finally, these studies vary with respect to the measure of fertility employed. Twenty of the 31 analyses endeavored to explain variation of children ever born or a cumulative birth rate measure, comparable to that employed in the present study. Among these studies, however, there is a vast difference in the details of the particular fer— tility measure. For example, some qualifications applied to cumulative fertility measure were "once married women," "husband present," variations in child—bearing age span, native-white women, standardization, etc. The second most frequently employed measure was the fertility ratio, at least some variation of it. Study Design of Empirical Studies The distinction of whether a study is "descriptive" or "causal" is sometimes a very thin line. Essentially if a study was designed to test specific hypotheses, it was considered "causal." Nine of the 31 studies were described as such (Table 13:15,21,22,25,26,27,28,30,31), and all of these have been published almost within the last decade. Another distinction on study design is relevant: ag— gregative vs. distributive studies. There were nine studies employing a distributive approach to the analysis of fertil— ity variation (Table 13:4,6,9,11,22,25,27,28,30). These studies generally applied correlation measures, simple, par- tial, and multiple, to the analysis of fertility. Interest— ingly there is not a one-to—one correlation of causal design 99 and distributive design. The early distributive studies were largely descriptive (Table 13:4,6,9,ll). If these two aspects of study design are correlated among the studies selected, there remain only five studies which apply both a causal design and a distributive framework (Table 13,22,25, 27,28,30) and of these only two employ an areal distributive approach (Table 13:22,27). These two analyses of fertility differentials, while they employ a design similar to that of the present study, are extremely limited as to the territo- rial scope they represent. Hughes concentrated on Tennes— see's total population and rural farm population, employing the county as his unit of analysis; Hashmi focuses on the Chicago Metropolitan area, with the census tract as the unit of analysis. While Hashmi claims to explain "urban fertil— ity differences in the United States," generalization from Chicago to the urban sector of the nation is quite tenuous. In view of these facts, an accurate assessment of the next step in the study of differential fertility should employ both a causal and areal distributive approach on a territo— rial level much more extensive than the state of metropol— itan area. As has been stated, the present study will in- volve national and divisional analyses for residential categories. Since this study focuses on fertility within residen- tial sectors, a discussion of how the review studies treat the residence variable is appropriate. While studies were 100 chosen partly on the basis of their contribution to the understanding of urban and rural fertility, there have appeared very few distributive studies which compare urban and rural fertility. There is a definite tendency among the studies selected to emphasize the investigation of urban fer- tility (Table l3:2,4,5,7,8,10,12,17,20,21,23,24,25,26,27,28, 29,31) and this is fairly representative of fertility studies in general. If the studies which equally emphasize urban and rural fertility are added (Table 13:1,3,13,14,16,18,19,30), there are 26 of the selected 31 studies which contribute to the understanding of urban fertility. Calculating in the same way, there are 18 studies which provide implications toward the understanding of rural fertility, although studies focusing on the rural components alone are relatively few (Table 13:6,9,11,15,22). It is unfortunate, however, that so many of these review studies in employing residential categories apply the aggregative approach rather than the distributive. As a result, most of the 31 review studies treat the residential populations as being homogeneous with respect to the variables related with a fertility measure. Relatively few studies provide insights as to the relation— ships one might find assuming variation within each residen- tial group and how they might differ in this respect. In spite of this deficiency, it is hoped that the findings and insights of the review studies will provide enough informa- tion on the nature of comparative variations within residen— tial groups to make proposition construction possible. 101 Summary of Findings, by Variable With the assistance of Table 14 a systematic review of the relevant findings is made more complete. Each of the general independent variables is discussed under separate sections. Upon a quick glance at Table 14 it can be seen that the three primary measure of socio—economic status have been most frequently employed in the 31 selected analyses of factors affecting fertility. Education has been included in 21 of the 31 studies, occupation is second appearing in 20 studies, and income runs close behind, appearing in 18 of the studies. The remaining three variables have appeared in sporadic fashion. Both age distribution of women and female employment have been employed in six of our 31 fertility studies; measures of distance have appeared in only five of the studies represented in this review. It must be mentioned that equal weight will not be granted to all studies reviewed. Studies which have inves— tigated fertility differences within residence groups or have study designs comparable to this study, e.g., causal and distributive, will weigh heavily in the development of propositions. These studies tend to be those most current, such as, studies by Hashmi, Hughes, Goldberg, and Duncan, to name a few. Let us now consider independently the pattern of association between fertility and the independent variables indicated in Table 14: distance, occupation, education, income, female employment, and age composition. 102 .mmuom .mm .ma manna ca uouau mm «Emu ous nousououom; oau¢>ca a“ .m.z m .uuoum wa no ca uuouao auao Baum . 9.5 m0 condunao coaxumn a caumaoza .o Ammauomemo m macov nodumwou omum>Ca " aasmm mmmau .mmooo vmoun sumo ca camumwwu mmum>ca "newsman uomamao .uaco canva3 so>o .coaumaou unu0>sa :aouwouoz .m .mom a ..m.z N .mmuo>ca noauau m "enuow own cvuma amen: x rom.- 0» ov.u mama“ m.u. .uuomsa umoe “muuo>Ca "00>OaQEm +oa c0503 mo x laws. on em. omcmu u.uv :Oaumaou o>auanom «.mme :a +oa 0mm mnemuom NO x sounaons .e ummwu 90: has nan uoouav unoao hm .QOaunaou uoouav awash a .mom .80» «.00 no uoau an ousmunan DAD! Q Hflflgkm . n ouuo>¢a mnouum .umaoum .mnooo vaoun m new “manncoauaa o>aucousa Hon couooaou moacsun avaaauuou so comma uoanaauu> unocaoaousa ou huaaauuou no amaaas0auuaou no oaauu finallflm Iou uaoao o: .omnooo aaflaamm a uauaoomu aam uo>o saouuouoz .N canny can» um30a .nmauoo auuauaao Iauma .onuo>:a msouuo :aouuouoz "aauum .amush can» can Homsouuo .aoaunaou noxoauuu ouHo>=a macho. «cankD unocmm .a scauaaomaoo cud unoEaOamem oamaoh oaoona :Oaunuscu abaummuooo ouauunaa auvuonund ¢3Da>ou .Qa OHAQB .l()3 ceaum 0n 0mu0>ca " aEmw mo 0E00 -aa Mecca mama amuos 0mu0>ca Lyon muouonma Ehmw can mumEumu new 0mu0>ca pan mascum .msouo aam macaw GOaumaou hcma a ocma "mua3 0c "mvma a h¢ma {F nomax .Na ouam. .aaa> m anon nom1 1 aouusoo :05: 00cm». .uuomfia no: IuomBa manamaamocm “muasmnua H030a mo @mimu 0km 0:3. ..uuow uo3ba vclma c0503 $_ :Oaumamn uuouaa. :mocsa .aa M .m.z mumsuo 1 1 .0mu0>ca maco 0wa3 GOauMaou o: "nonsmam “sman .uuou .mmamsou coccman .aa00 :uon :0n3 um00 macaw «uuouac 1 m masm Ixo 0mm0>sa «mausou cnm3ou uu0xomun IIIIPII 1 1 ICOaumaou o: upmcsmam .Dmss can» ummcouum mo» ca NGOMumwo . wa0>0a ummm: um00x0 .0mu0>:a “ova: Ixu van .0mu0>:a 1 couma0£3 1 0mu0>§a "camnmsm. 0mu0>Ca "unmnmam cuwzbu mucoccmb 1 a uuuax .oa 11‘ ummao uom4.m00. d _ .nuu abuu 0>OE unmoauacmamw .cmamlco: .0mu0>:a 0mu0>¢a ".00 no mm aamu mmumu Icon nm~lmm 05m” "mmma .0EOUCa Sham uumm mm new .9800 .uuom um030a umwmnom w «elma coao3_fim muammo hum 0mmu0>< .mum .num guano: 1 mmauao .ou0021umasvc0mom .m 4‘ .m9: can» ucmuuo Ba 1 1 1 once .0900 n.0ma3 1 "mmmmmm .ma0>0a h .aaou uOu HmmHo 00: 1 van 0mu0>ca "camnmsm 1 won an s0>0 .0mu0> . ummax a Isa haum0a0 ”omas 1 nonmaons .m 3H swan: new mucouuomaa ca H030a amazoa swan: «nonma .um> ucmuuomaa unOE 09cm mzbnn .3»: Mom gnaw cmnu .uumm M0 uaooca «scam unmao unwaUImuouu “umoHu |3Oa nuofiumu ..mmsuoo Imu0u0 ”cuaammm uo: 0mu0>sa "amunu summco: new 0mu0> awash “mommmau humus “haco .uuac aamfin Isa «amusm «ceaumauu :a aamfim nan .ouu0> .m.m can .HHOU pan noouac nonunao mo» : Isa swans “NaaEmm ouu0>Ca sang: nouas van 0nu0>sa "cmnub uanax .n scauaaomaou 0m¢ 0:03a0amam oanalm oaouca ceaumosom scaummnooo 00cmuman anvuonu=< nossaucoonnea canoe 1(14 cuouum ua0H0 on "amma 0200 a 5 Eumm now swan a mcoaummsuoo Eumuco: I am mam .0mu0>: 0mu0> macaw .uuou 30a ammo umvma oaooca aaEmm Isa msouun "ouaz uxo coaumamu Hm0a0 oz aaanmuo .ma 0mu0>ca mm can mzm 1 "m 0mquca aaaEmu .mEa amsvm mo .05u0 can» :mnus ca 0wu0>ca 1 swans .muo .uwmo Eumm 0mu0>Ca w .maooo unmulmmouu who: .mmsuoo 00a>u0m 1 .0uOE xuo3 c0803 .mv u0>o c0503 "HmmH “m.©:mnm5£ can» a .u0a0 qu ceauamo 1 .m H0>O noun can ms: mo 0&OUCa .uuomfia OHOE n.0mm3 Ixm .muufiumw cmcu 1 Iaanu c053 100u0u osoa amuoe nomuw>c “0mu0>:a "panama: .uumm u0£mac .uonma caumaonz 1 nonma ca :0503 mumnm "mvma IHHEmm1 museum .mmu aam ea Eumw .mQSOHm 00:0ca w uwmax 1 now u030a .uumm mmmuca amcos amuoa1 0mu0>ca ummau "mmaz Imou aam ca 0mu0>ca .aaanmuu .ma w J 0mu0> 1 Ina 00a£3|0>aumc . . “0mu0>ca .mom amuoa camumcaou .ma . ceaummmmuo sun» 1 ucmquQEa whoa n.uu0w _ cu mmcmnu 8 acaumauu muwuonma Emma can» 0>auamoa no ouamm .uuuw ~03Oa uweumw :a .mQSOum .mmu “museum .wmu aam ca 1 aam .momm aam .GOau,am0au0a0 uo coaumwoxm _ Imamu 0mu0>¢a "mwaz :ua3 ceaumawu 0mu0>ca nomax .ma _ toaaaxmcs can» . .uuwu u030a .uonma Emma .cOaaaxm .uuom “030a Hoeumu "acoum luoan oasocooo msba w IaOu acaumaou 0mu0>ca Smmm .ma 1r muouonma .mmmau macaw .muwac shun can» .uumw mo macauomuucou mo uoaba uafihmw unmsuoo manm :a scaumaou amusuasoaumm “acoau 0mu0>sa um0a0 303m Immoxm nua3 .mmma h¢ma m oema "0ma3 .ovma .oama onu0>sa uuoummz .va acaumaau oouo>ca »¢ 00 conmmaaoo museum cocaoaa .0231 «.2308 .umm How .cva o: .GOaumaou nacho ucuuuaucoo a: on nova) «0 00¢ .:0aana0u unoao 0: now ooaaouusou museum .msouo onaz auxcan .ma coauanoaaou om< ucoahoamau cacaom oaoosa scaumoscm soaumnuuuo ouanuuao auvuonuad coucaucoou-ea canny 105 ucmuauacmam Ir 0:0 0mu0>0a "0ma3 mucmumaa can “mucmumae can scan: swans msoc0ma©sa now u0mca00am msoc0macca Ham 00a» a0>0a 0m0aa00 Ham 0:0 Imaou uoouac "panama: .0x0 .0mu0>:a u0ua3 amavooum .om . ma£000a00a0u u0mcouun 1 mucmumaa .00u0>:a 1 0mu0> "0wa3 "vacuum mm 00: _ Ina mucmumae ..m.z pan 00am m0uacmnus m0uacmnu0 .0mu0>0a .0mu0>0a mucmumma 1 m0ad000 aam ”panama: .m0am000 aam “camnnsm mu0nwa00 .ma . .aa00 m 0>auamoa van 00H0>Ga . IILILII. . ma0>0a u0mms .0x0 "ccmnmsm «a0>0a .HHOU ma0>0a u0mms .0mu0>ca Hosanna: .0x0 0mu0>sa "0.0ua3 .0000X0 0mu0>ca 00amm0m .vm . mmma 00:» Nmma 00:» 0mu0> 1 0HOE 0wu0>ca hmma Isa 0u05 hmma nu00a0 1 0mu0>0a umoao 100mm aam 0mu0>ca mwo no: mmo nm¢lm~ 0mm _ smma u08.3 o>onm 1o¢-m~ uoouao .emuma uoouao .vaama own _ uoouac uQ0UX0 0mu0> 0mm 0mu0>0a caumu 0mu0>sa.om a ovma -aa mmma "panamam .uumw amps: u0ua3 oaumu .uu0m gonna nouax .mm 0mu0>ca 000 m o>au mo anon :04 mo mums amazon: ”mm ..m.z ups .ma: "mm 1m «o .uuoou upon 00009 m we cam ..smam um0£ma£ ..mom amuOu can 0>au 000 .mom ca 0mu0>0a .+mm 0mm amuOu "osoosa aaamm new cmac0a ”00am: nonmam .NN .mucmumaa munmumaa 00am “.m.z Show 000 mouacmnun 00u0>0a .m00acmnu0 zuon. .00000 no 0800 nucmumaa Sham no h.w.z 009 .0mu0> Isa :05» ucmuuomaa n0uacmnu0 now 00a» Isa moansoo aam "000m 0HOE .0mu0>:a "ova: Imaou unnuauanmau oz muonuaou .aN 0wa3 .ououonma Shaw 00:0 00:0 unnuuomaa 000a .uuom u030a Hoaumu 00>a3 mcaxuo3 00 "vsmnupm .aoeouca “finance: .n> Shaw aa0n ucmuuomfia 000E 000 .0mu0>:a "Naaamm .nmsc mo aouucouv 0nu0>ca vuoumoum Imamu a mo 000 ”ouu0>sa unmUaMacmamco: 00m 0600 .m.m a .HHoo “umaoum Shannon .couma0zz "0wa3 mo usoaaoamau. 0>auamom "cannnsm pan 0mu0>ca "ouaz macaw .uuac 0avuaa .005000uh .om scauauomeoo out 000:50amafi camsfim osouaa coaumosvu :Oauamauuo anchorage oocuuuao cuscauGOUIuva canoe {I‘ll l()6 0m0auume 00 0mm 0 .mauuo ..0500 now aouucoo 00:3 .a0u .000 mcouu0 "+NN um 00:3 .uom .a~u¢a um voauumfi 0ma3 0003 IPI 0000>0a "0000000 +N~ um ooauumfi 00:3 .000 .auuea 00mm um voauuna 00m) 00m” 0000>0a ”000A0sm 00uuaao .0m5000 .000 "+NN 0mm 0003 000%: “am Ica 00mm 00 00auudl 00a: 0003 0000>0H .05 :2: .233 “300N000 00w 0000a .0000ca00u Sham 0a 000m0ouum .00auma00 00u0>0m "0ma3 no .0000 ha 0ua3 00 0000000000 00 000 050 0000000 0000> I0a 0500 «mammmmm .hz Mow 0000:00uum “00noumxuan Show 000 .000 Shaw 000 00u0> I0a 0000000000 "00am .om 00a» Ia000500 amuaumfi uOu mcaaaouucoo uuouap .0000 amuauma “0000> I0a 03000 0000 .0000 amuou ..u0a 00a005 . mo 00000a0 "Naaamm 0mmauumfi mo 00% maumo 000020 .uuomfia .a0u 000 “.000> va uo aa .0H» +oa coauuua «0a u0 0009 :00 .00» mum c0auuma "0mm 0.0ua3 .a0u 0000>0a h00a00a00> Va 0a sum “0 0a 0003 sum «00> +oa v0auuafl "00a00a00> 0a 0a sum ”0 0a 0003 can .0u> mum c0auuma "Oua3 HO ufluwuu fig 0a 00 sum .00» +oa rayon :uoa .00» mum "mam tha000 .00> ea 0a «w 00 upon :00 .aa» +oa no no 0003 vnm .0u> mum 0a “0000>0a "0ma3 “anon :04 .aa» +oa .ouon numa .ma» mum "0a0ma000 .um> 0a 0a "00000 0 0a .0.2 .00» mum 00auuma "0000000 00000 0000 0a .uuomaa hu0> 000 “anon nu¢a an» +oa 1: 5 3E ..0u> mum ”000n000 “muon nuaa .nua +oa .0a 0a 000A 000 .00» mum 00a0000 «00a; .mN 0““ .a00 000 “70000 a .3000a .00000. ..0000 umgman .0msoum 0mm “code a 00:00: .uoouav "000300 a000aunu0000 .uuomaa .a0u nun ".0000 000 03000a 00000 I000 mcavaong 0000» I0a mcouua «combam IE0 +ma 00in: R 00000000Ia .a0u 00 qua a.0500 00000 neon unavaoso coda Inaou uoouav ..uu 8.85 x .1050 00a30 Iaum> aHMINb .uuom Iaa .aou 000. “A0I00 I0a 00000000 mCaUaon 00>0. 000023 000.130 .vouoamloo .m00 +m~ 00am! 8 «00am! 000 Inuuomfla .a0u 0auuaa «n.0000 000 .00a 00000000 unauaoao .m.z .00a0 «uoauau .bhoa 0.0nua % «onuob 10a .0uu000 w .uoum R.»000auaaou canal N058 000000 000000 000 030mmaax . 00-00000 .uuomla .aou sum. «.0060 a 0I001 .aa 000 aouu. I000 £00.30. huao «0 000000. luau 000000a0 al§000 F .hN 00aua0omsoo om: u00lh0amafl OaQIUh OEOUGH coauauaou 00a0005000 1 000000an lbwuvuozuud voucauaoouuva manna 107 Distance.—-Studies which have related fertility to distance from urban areas are few, and even fewer from met— ropolitan centers. Thus, most of these studies place their findings in the realm of "urban influence." Nevertheless, these analyses of fertility have been highly descriptive, for want of a theoretical framework and a better comprehen- sion of just what distance does measure. Often "urban dominance theory" is only an implicit theoretical framework underlying such studies. Let us review what the empirical studies of fertility declare overall to be the relationship between fertility and distance. In Table 14 there are two early studies which employ data for no later than 1930. They have obtained fairly con- sistent results. Brunner and Kolb (Table 14:3) investigated fertility levels by tiers of counties from 18 large urban centers (all but three having populations over 50,000) and found a relatively clear positive association when consider— ing total population and total rural population by county tiers. The contrast of rural-farm and rural-nonfarm by distance found some exceptions to the positive association of fertility and distance, but the pattern persisted. Thompson and Jackson (Table 14:6) focused on tiers of town- ships rather than counties and considered several other variables to denote economic conditions of rural communities. Distance and a measure of the percent of the rural popula— tion dwelling on farms were used as indices of the degree of 108 isolation of a rural community from the influence of cities. Although exceptions appeared, the predominant relationship was a positive one. Thompson and Jackson, interestingly, noted the possibility that distance was merely reflecting variations in general economic status of communities and, in turn, economic conditions measured to some degree the isolation of rural communities. Rosenquist and Schafft (Table 14:9) considered rural— farm parts of counties in Texas with respect to fertility. There was a tendency toward a positive relation, but it was not necessarily a clear, linear one. Duncan (Table 14:11) considered the location of villages (indicative of the rural- nonfarm population) in Pennsylvania with respect to metropol- itan and urban centers in non—metropolitan counties. The location of villages was positively related with respect to fertility levels, but the effects of location were reduced to negligible proportions when rent and village size were held constant. As did Thompson and Jackson, Duncan's results hint the possibility of location actually reflecting differences in socio—economic status. Finally, Hashmi also found a positive association among census tracts of the Chicago metropolitan area, but this case does not pertain to our immediate problem, since his results focus on the pat— tern within a metropolitan center rather than between the metropolitan center and the hinterland counties. 109 Two possibilities appear in terms of interpretation of what distance measures. On the one hand, it may merely be a "conglomerate" variable which subsumes several latent factors highly correlated with distance. On the other hand, the conventional procedure is to couch the explanation in terms of metropolitan dominance, rural isolation, urban in— fluence and the like. It is understood that influence wanes with increasing distance from the centers of influence. Two variations occur on this explanation and they take the form of the "homogeneous area" vs. "nodal area" issue discussed by Bogue and touched upon in the first chapter of this thesis of non-random distribution of certain attributes in space.8 The "homogeneous" region stresses the internal homogeneity of delineated areas in contrast to comparable regions. The metropolitan community, or "nodal" region, stresses non—random distribution of attributes within the area along a continuum of distance from the central city. These two positions may be merged if homogeneity is under- stood to refer to the spread of dominance within the region, a notion directly opposed to the concept "urban influence" which is viewed as diminishing or "trailing off" with in— creasing distance. As a result, the entire metropolitan 8Donald J. Bogue, "Population Distribution," in P. Hauser, and O. D. Duncan, The Study of ngulation (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1959), pp. 393-394. Discussion of this issue appears in this thesis on pp. 67-69. 110 region is considered dominated by the metropolitan center with equal force. Concern should not be so much for how far does the influence of the center extend but what is the impact of the centers influence on the structure of the region. Metropolitan regions may differ, then, in the exten— siveness of dominance reflected by size of the metropolitan center, but the non—random distribution of attributes within the metropolitan region results from the prevading dominance within both the urban and rural hinterlands. This last ntion, in turn, absorbs the earlier comment that distance reflects a number of latent factors. On this basis, it is expected that fertility, as well as many other attributes of rural and urban communities within the metropolitan regions, will reflect a non-random pattern of distribution. In view of the consistent positive relation between fertility and distance apparent in the empirical studies discussed above, a strong positive relationship_is also expected in our analysis; i.e., with increasing distance from a metropolitan center, an increase in fertility within all residence groups of the hinterland. Furthermore, a mea— sure to differentiate size of metropolitan center must be applied to the distance measure. Finally, considering the necessity of subordinating most attributes revealing non- random distributive patterns in the metropolitan region to dominance exerted by metropolitan centers, the distance mea— sure as a "conglomerate" index must receive primary impor— tance among all variables considered, again, for all 111 residence groups. On the other hand, as some of the empir— ical studies indicate it may very well occur that the rela— tive importance measure is reduced considerably when other variables are held constant, such as, education, income, etc. In such a case we would conclude that distance reflects dif- ferences in socio—economic status and, therefore, has no predictive value by itself. Hence, there remains the dilemma as to the relative importance of distance in predict— ing fertility levels. There must also be asserted, then, a contradictory proposition, that distance may also reflect a slight positive association with fertility and low relative importance in accounting for fertility variation in both urban and rural areas. This conclusion suggests the need for further research. Occupation.—-Occupational data have been available through census much longer than any other criterion of socio- economic status. This explains why the early studies of differential fertility, for the most part, selected occupa— tional measures to relate with fertility (Table 14:1,2). Occupation was employed in these early studies as a measure of "social class" or "social status." Since that time, additional measures have been developed as indices of social status (education, income, monthly rent, etc.) to complement and at times replace an occupational measure. Grabill, Kiser, and Whelpton have noted some inher- ent weaknesses in the use of occupational group of the 1“ 112 husband as an index of socio-economic status:9 (1) wives do not describe their husbands' occupations with sufficient accuracy; (2) unlike educational attainment (but like income status), occupation is subject to change, and a previous occupation may be in some instances more influential with respect to fertility than the present; (3) whereas educa- tional status and income are quantitative and continuous, occupational groups are more qualitative and discrete; (4) mxrupational group of husband, by definition cannot be applied.to single women. In addition, the broad occupational groups themselves contain a wide variety of specific occupa- tions and a wide range of social and economic gradation. It could be argued that, compared to the early studies, at Fussent this variation within each of the broad occupational 9Toups has widened because of the continuing diversification °f explaining fertility levels. It appears from Table ll4-that wife's educational level is more popular in the eHHPirical studies selected for review. Eighteen of the 21 Stlldixes employing one or more education measures used a measure for the wife. Only ten of these studies employed a husband' S educational attainment measure (Table l4:4,8,10,18, 20’24'25 28 3o 31) and all but tw f . , , o 0 these also employed a "leas tire for the wife, only three empirical studies used a ‘ .U ... 120 Combined measure for both husband and wife's educational level (Table l4:8,9,10). Furthermore, in several studies it was concluded from the evidence of the results that wife's educational attainment level is much more influential than the husband's in predicting fertility (Table 14:8,10,18,20, 25,30). Because of this, the educational level of the couple always revealed the same relationship with fertility as that between wife's education and fertility. Overall, educational attainment, by whatever measure, tencm»to show a persistent inverse relationship with fertil— ity. For all three measures mentioned above, studies which reveal a clear inverse relationship far outnumber those which either found exceptions to the inverse relation, just as the "J" curve for occupational data, or found a relation- ship not statistically significant. In support of this Observation it is to be noted that wife's educational attain- ment.lewel maintained this strong inverse relationship with fertilrity during the period 1940-50, in spite of the fact that charing this time the proportional increases in fertil— ltY were directly related to educational attainment.15 This Fmtteril occurred in all residence categories, although more pronounced in urban areas. Kiser later found educational differentials in fertility widened in 1950—57 (Table 14:23) - \fl Eton 15C. V. Kiser, "Changes in Fertility by Socio— Cnnigz Status during 1940—1950, " Milbank Memorial Fund Qu \~§E:E£i£_JZ. XXXIII (October, 1955), 417. 121 Both Kiser and Grabill (Table 14:16,l8) found a clear inverse relationship for wife's educational level within all age groups and residence groups. In an earlier study, Kiser (Table 14:7) found the relationship stronger in his rural sample. Rosenquist and Schafft with data of approximately the same period also found a relatively sig— nificant negative correlation for the rural-farm part of counties in Texas (Table 14:9). Hughes (Table 14:22) like- wise found in Tennessee that for the rural-farm part of counties educational attainment (using a median as did Rosenquist and Schafft) has a strong inverse association with fertility (revealing the highest beta coefficient of the variables in the equation). Goldberg in two important studies (Table l4:21,25) found that the usual inverse relationship of fertility to Socio~economic variables is largely due to farm migrants in urban areas. It is worth noting, however, that he finds "onlyeeducation survives as a status variable capable of differentiating levels of fertility among the two-generation ‘urbanites."16 Thus, among both the second-generation urban- .ites and the farm migrants education possesses much predic- 'tj”e Power, whereas occupation and income do not. However, 'iIlthiS and a later study by Goldberg (Table 14:25), educa— tllon indicated a stronger inverse relationship for the farm 1___‘____________ l . I 6DaVid Goldberg, op. c1t., p. 218. 122 migrants than for second—generation urbanites. Duncan (Table 14:30) supported this residential difference in find- ing that the inverse relationship of fertility and wife's education is more pronounced for wives of farm residence and farnlbackground. A study of Freedman and Slesinger (Table 14: 26) concurred with the initial finding of Goldberg that edu- cation remains inversely associated with fertility in the "indigenous" nonfarm group, whereas income indicated a posi— tive relationship. Finally, Hashmi's study (Table 14:27) focuses on a single urban area and concludes that education and income together are the most important factors in urban fertility, together accounting for 71 percent of fertility variance. Education in his study indicates a strong nega— tiVeCorrelation with fertility, plus producing the higher betatzoefficient over income. In conclusion, these empirical studies strongly SuPport the expectation of a strong inverse association in all residence groups, in fact, stronger than such socio- economic status indicators as income and occupation. More- over, the relative importance of this variable compared anmng residence groups is difficult to determine, primarily leecause the relative importance of educational attainment Should be high in all categories of residence. Some empiri- C:al StUdies suggest that educational attainment is more .ElEEEEEEHE_in the rural sectors (Table l4:21,22,25,26,30) in e"(pl-aiming variation in fertility levels. 0' -v on 123 Income.-—Before discussion of the findings on income from the selected list of empirical studies, a review of the inherent characteristics of income as a variable is appro— priate. In contrast to education, and like occupation, income is a changeable measure; but unlike occupation, it is quantitative. Second, the usual measures of income consider income only for the previous year. The sensitivity of such a measure, it would seem, is dependent upon events which have transpired in the immediate past. Education, in con- trast, is a more cumulative index. It is, therefore, neces— sary to be cautious of results when applying income measures to the study of cumulative fertility. Kiser explained his conclusion of the importance of income over occupation and Education in his study simply because income and fertility measures pertained to the previous year, whereas occupation 17 and education did not. Third, it would seem that there is a tendency for income to increase with advancing age. Similar to occupational group, a previous income level may have more influence on number of children ever born that CUrrent income. Finally, a measure of family income is con- founded by working wives which tends to raise income level while simultaneously diminishing the fertility level. \‘V (B . 17C. V. Kiser, Group Differences in Urban Fertility altimore: williams and Wilkins, 1942), pp. 172—3. 124 Many indirect indices of income level have been devised, e.g., relative income, rental value, place of living, welfare, tax lists, etc., but our primary concern is with family income per se. The popularity of income as a measure of socio-economic status, like education, has in— creased in current studies. Three variables in measurement have been employed: family income, husband's (sometimes head of household) income, and wife's income (seldom used until recently). The relationships of these measures with fertility and among themselves are much more complex than for educational attainment measures. The confounding effects of husbands' and wives' educational level on the Couples' educational attainment level are not as great as that for husbands' and wives' income levels and family in- Come. The relationship of income and fertility as eXpressed by empirical studies in Table 14 employing an income measure, is not clear. There are 18 of the 31 studies in the table Whleh consider at least one measure of income level. Hus- band's and family income have been used in about the same nunIber of cases. In an early study (Table 14:5) family in— Come for urban areas exhibited an inverse relationship with fel‘tility, but Kiser (Table 14:7) very early found the ten— dency for upper income classes to be directly related with f . . er1:::n_lity level. Succeeding research established a similar pattern of relationship (Table l4:10,23,24,3l) primarily for Urb an areas, however. 125 Some provocative data on income and fertility appeared in the Current Population Surveys of 1949 and 1952 (Table l4:18,l9). The 1949 Survey found a sharp inverse relation of number of own children under five per 1,000 Imuried.women 15—49 to total money income of families. The 1952:3urvey, however, found no corresponding inverse rela— tion between the number of own children under five per 1,000 married men 20-59 and money income of the man. In this same survey children ever born per 1,000 women, age 45 or older, married and husband present, was found to be inversely asso- ciated with husband's income, but for women age 15—44, no such relation was found. The difficulties of interpreta- tion arise from the variety of measures used for fertility and income level as well as the failure to control for high fertility groups such as rural—farm and non—whites. These data raised the question, however, of a possible transition at least for urban areas toward a positive relationship of fertility to income level. The rural elements appeared to maintain the inverse pattern of relationship. In the same publication (Table 14:18) data were presented indicating an inverse relationship between farm operator family income in ‘19‘49 and fertility. Using 1950 county data for Tennessee, Hughes (Table 14:22) found a similar inverse association for the rural-farm parts of counties. Hughes in the same source, however, established a Po ' - - sJ.t_‘1_ve relationship for income of the total population 4.. Il' ... ‘v 126 among the counties of Tennessee. This correlation was strong with income second among five beta coefficients. Other indications of a positive association are available, employing relatively current data. The Growth of American Families Study (Table 14:20) uncovered a positive relation for husband's income, although it was not significant. The authors, however, explain that whereas "the average number of children born by 1955 was actually larger for the high- income groups than for those with low incomes . . . this differential is due to the influence of age--the higher in— come couples are older and so the wives had an opportunity to bear more children by the time of the interview."18 The same study found a stronger inverse relation between family M and fertility. The authors, in addition, pose the fOJ-lowing explanation as to why the relationship of fertil— itY to income is somewhat stronger when family income rather than husband's income is used: It is because the couples with low family income are more likely to be those in which the wife does not work and has relatively many births, while the couples with high family incomes are more heavily weighted with those that include working wives who have relatively few chil- dren. Because the stronger relationship of fertility to family income is due primarily to the influence of the Wife's employment status and not to the family income N, we cannot say that family income alone has much .‘Lnfluence on fertility. \~\—— 18 Fam' Ronald Freedman, P. K. Whelpton, and A. A. Campbell, McGLl Planning, SterilitL and Paulation Growth (New York: raw'fllll. 1959), pp. 296—7. 19 _ 334$, pp. 302-3. 127 Others have echoed this same explanation that wife's income strongly enhances the inverse relationship between family income and fertility (Table l4:7,l8,26,27) . The subsequent studies associated with the Growth of American Families Study, therefore, moved to relating husband's and wife's income separately with fertility. Using husband's income Goldberg (Table l4:21,25) found the relationship for second-generation urbanites tended toward the positive, whereas farm migrants indicated the traditional inverse rela— tion. The investigation of wife's income and fertility is relatively recent, largely because the working wife has become such a common phenomenon today. Freedman and Slesinger (Table 14:26) found a consistent negative relation 0f fertility to wife's income, being strong in the first years of marriage, but a tendency toward the positive for busband's income. Deborah Freedman (Table 14:28) discovered a Positive relation only when employing husband's "relative" income (the ratio of a man's actual income to the income Customary in his socio-economic reference group). Kunz (Table 14:31) reinforces this with the discovery that con- trolling for education occupation, and age at marriage makes this POSitive relationship between fertility and husband's inCome even stronger. Surprisingly, Hashmi indicates a positive relation for an urban area even when employing m incOme (Table 14:27). Kitagawa (Table 14:29) employed f - . amlly income for an urban area but found it related . ~ 128 inversely with total fertility, but positively when marital fertility was employed. This, apparently, was due to the tendency for women in the high-status groups to marry later than women in the lower—status groups. In conclusion, on the basis of the above evidence, it would not be surprising to discover a moderate positive correlation between income and fertility in urban areas even when family income is applied. Rural areas will retain the more traditional inverse relationship. The income of women, on the other hand, would tend to consistently correlate in— versely with fertility in both residence groups. In terms of relative importance of income variables, although the eVidence has not been fully discussed, analyses of the empirical studies suggest that income would rank below edu— cational attainment but above an occupational measure. The income of the wife, considering that little research has been done in this area, will not carry much weight in an anEllysis involving other major socio—economic variables. HOWever, if family income is employed as the income measure, Controlling for women's income as well as women employed in the labor force and age composition should reduce the rela— 1Ve Jimportance of family income in accounting for fertility v - . . . . afiance. Furthermore, Since family income is perhaps a poor In . . eEnsure to apply to the rural-farm population, and Wife's in ~ . . m 13 perhaps more of an urban phenomenon, it is expected 129 that family income is relativeiy more important in the urban sector than the rural—farm. Female empioyment.--Interest in the effects of work- ingxnomen on fertility levels is very recent. Although Vfimlpton had employed this variable in an analysis of census tract data in eight northern cities in the 1930's and had found a strong inverse relation, as well as the fact that it Mes one of the most important variables in explaining fertil- ity differences, most research using this variable is recent. zuxhough Table 14 denotes that only six of the empirical studies (Table l4:4,18,20,27,28,30) have included a measure fluffemale employment, the studies which have been conducted are quite intensive in dealing with this factor. .A11.six studies report a relatively strong inverse relation of fertility to women employed in the labor force. Whelpton (Table 14:4) was the first to point out the diffi- Culty of specifying the direction of the cause-effect rela— tiOnship regarding fertility and female employment. That is: doxmmnen work because they prefer it to marriage and Chi-ldbearing or because of economic pressure of the family? A r‘elated question is whether women tend is whether women tetufl to keep>the number of children low in order to work or does; the fact that they are employed in the work force keep fart:ility.low? It appears that a selective process may be the rnore 1cxgica1 explanation, i.e., the labor force tends to Se . . . leaczt womeri of low fertility than Vice versa. Freedman 130 (Table 14:20) explains the relationship with reference to fecundity: for subfecund women the small family leaves the wife free to work, for the fecund, on the other hand, advan- tages of employment may influence working wives to limit their families. Grabill finds that age of children, and not merely whether children are present, is very important to labor force participation of women (Table 14:18). This relation- ship is more pronounced when fertility is measured as "own children under five per married women," than "children ever born." Thus, after children reach an age when close super— vision of the mother is not required, there is less inter- ference with participation in the labor force. This pattern is distinctly different from an earlier pattern in which women tended to drop entirely out of the labor force to enter marriage and raise a family. A census publication describes a life pattern of married women which may act as a confounding factor in the relationship of fertility to labor force participation of women: In the last decade or so . . . a life pattern seems to be developing among many married women in which they work until the arrival of the first baby, temporarily withdraw from the labor force while their children are young, and then return to the labor force after Sheir children are old enough to require little care.2 20U. S. Bureau of Census, U. S. Census of Ropulation: 1950, Vol. IV, Special Reports, Part 5, Chapter C,"Ferti1ity," p. 11. 131 Such a pattern would tend to reduce the importance of labor force participation among women of long marriage duration. This is precisely what Freedman found in a recent study (Table 14:28). In the group of women married 5-9 years, wife's labor force status was negative and relatively impor- tant in predicting fertility; in the group married 10 or more years, no significant relationship was revealed. Another factor which may compound results rests in whether marital status is considered in the measure of labor force participation. Grabill (Table 14:18) finds that chil- dren ever born per 1,000 ever-married women 15—49 is lower for women in the labor force, regardless of marital status, in all residence groups. If only ever-married women are considered in the measurement of labor force participation, omitting partially a segment of the female labor force which may be subfecund, the relationship of fertility and labor force participation would tend to be stronger. Thus, relat- ing a measure of the participation of 3ii_women in the labor force would tend to reduce the predictive power of this independent variable in all residence categories. A major share of the interest in female labor force participation and its effects on fertility has been focused on urban areas. This is understandable in view of the fact that in 1950 the proportion of white women age 18 to 49 employed in the labor force was 37 percent for the urban component of the nation, 26 percent for the rural—nonfarm, 132 and only 17 percent for the rural—farm population. Women employed in the labor force is more largely an urban phenom- enon. Hashmi (Table 14:27) found for Chicago census tracts that employment status of women ranked only below income and education in relative importance in determining fertility levels. Furthermore, Grabill speculates that: It seems possible that the employment opportunities for women in rural—farm areas may interfere less with house— hold activities than is the case in urban and rural— nonfarm areas. It is also likely that by virtue of higher fertility and by virtue of a greater tendency to take parents and relatives into the household, the pres- ence of children per se does not tend to tie the mother to the home as much in rural-farm areas as in the other cases. If this is an accurate observation, it might be argued that women in the labor force would not affect fertility as much in rural areas as in urban areas. Thus, the stronger inverse relation should appear within the urban sector and the rela- tive importance of women in the labor force should be greater in the urban population than the rural. In conclusion, it is expected that female employment will reveal a stronger negative relationship with fertiligy in urban than rural areas. Female employment, because of confounding factors, will have ggeateripredictive power in urban areas than in rural areas and perhaps will be of less importance than educational attainment and family income, but above occupation and female income for urban areas. 21W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, op. cit., p. 265. 133 Age composition.—-Age composition of women in the child bearing years has been dealt with in past studies as a secondary factor, generally in the form of standardizing the fertility rate. This procedure, it is suspected, is usually performed so automatically that the implications for the results of the analysis are not seriously considered. The fact that age is dealt with in this fashion implies that age is possibly a major disturbing factor in the relation of fertility to conventional socio-economic variables, although in many cases it is impossible or difficult to determine the effects of age. Age not only bears heavily upon fertility because of its biological foundation, but essentially it provides bench— marks in the life cycle, and indirectly reflect such socio- economic variables as income, female employment, occupation, etc. Age is used simultaneously in qualifying, refining or isolating dependent and independent measures used in fertil- ity analysis. As examples, it is customary to limit the measure of fertility only to the child—bearing ages of women; occupation is represented only for employed adult persons: educational attainment is limited to adults beyond college age, etc. The charge could be made that age has seldom been employed seriously as a primary variable in fertility analysis, with the exception of a handful of studies. Because of this fact, there seems to be very little evidence with respect to the explicit relationship of fertil— ity to age. 134 In Table 14, six studies of fertility are listed for review that have employed some measure of age composition of women in the childbearing age span. Even in these studies the results on age either have been omitted, ignored, or dealt with lightly. The Whelpton study of the 1930's (Table 14:4) found fertility associated with the percentage of white women 15—44 who were age 20—34 in an inverse direc— tion for five of the eight cities studied. Three later studies concluded that age of women had little to contribute to the explanation of fertility differences (Table 14:9,11, 13). Rosenquist and Schafft found no significant relation— ship among the rural—farm parts of counties in Texas when employing a measure of the percentage of women 15—44 in the age group 25-29. Duncan used the percentage of women 15—44 who were ages 25-34 ("the most fertile ages") in analyzing village population in Pennsylvania, but found the age factor of negligible importance. Dinkel controlled for age of wife in each broad occupational group by region but concluded that no additional information was yielded. Two recent studies obtained more favorable results. Freedman (Table 14:28) included wife's age in a multiple regression analysis of fourteen variables. No direction of association is reported, but for the group married 5—9 years -Lts beta coefficient ranked fourth in relative importance; fttr women married ten or more years, age of wife appeared urljnmmmtant. Assuming that women of the younger ages in the cblind-bearing period would tend to fall into the "married 135 5-9 years" group, the results suggest that proportions of women in the younger ages are more important in determining fertility levels. Hashmi (Table 14:27) recorded a very high positive association between the proportion of age groups and fertility, i.e., high proportions of older age groups correlated with high fertility levels or, translated, high proportions of younger age groups correlated with low fer— tility levels (an inverse association). For the metropol— itan area of Chicago the relative importance of age compo— sition ranked below education, income, and female employment and above occupation, distance, nativity, and ethnicity. In conclusion, the review of empirical studies seems to lead to a consideration of age as a relatively unimpor- tant factor in fertility analysis. It could be argued that age distribution of women of child—bearing age is probably very similar within residence groups, though admitting regional differences, largely due to a selective migration factor which would tend to reduce proportions of young women (largely single) in the rural-farm group and pad this age group in the urban and rural-nonfarm groups. Considering the well-documented fact that changes in fertility in the last few decades have been due largely to earlier marriage aindthe tendency to have children at younger ages, plus the ability of women to conceive being strongest between the 136 ages 18 and 24,22 it appears that the greatest fluctuation for cumulative fertility is in the early ages of the child— bearing period. In addition, consider the fact that age is not only an important factor per se, but also is highly related to other socio-economic variables. Finally, distri- bution of women by age could be expected to have a direct limiting effect on fertility in the sense that children will not be born when the supply of mothers of the peak reproduc- tive ages is relatively low. Upon consideration of these aspects, it seems reasonable to expect that age variation in proportions of women in the childbearing ages would be rela- tively important in all residence grogps. Furthermore, on the basis of the two most recent studies reviewed above, 3 strong inverse relationship will occur between proportions in the young childbearing ages (say ages 15—24) and cumula— Eive fertiligy, but will not be strong at later ages where fertility rates level off in the lager age groups of the reproduction age span. Resume of Empirical Propositions from Intensive Review of Empirical Studies As mentioned at the beginning of this chapter, one function of a review of literature is the development and menstruction of a set of meaningful propositions. We are especially looking for urban-rural differences in the \— 22Ibid., pp. 29—37. ,_._ . 137 association of independent variables and fertility. Several propositions have been asserted in the review of findings of the thirty-one empirical studies categorized by the six broad independent variables considered in this analysis. The resume of propositions will follow the same order as presented above. Distance Although the studies reviewed above failed to treat the relationship of fertility to distance from cities in any way other than description, additional comments enable the extraction of more substantial propositions. Even among the studies considered, a direct relationship between fertility and distance is quite consistent for all residence groups. Since it is the intention of this study to consider an ecological framework as a theoretical position, it is assumed that distance is an overriding factor in all residence cate— gories, and, therefore, a very important variable in predict- ing fertility levels, especially when size of the influencing metropolitan center is taken into account. It is possible, 'however, that controlling for several other variables, such as, income, education, etc., will reduce the relative impor— tance of ecological distance as a predictor of fertility Variation. The following are propositions for the distance me—‘asure: l. Fertility is directly related to distance from metro— politan centers (differentiated by size) within both residence categories. 138 2. Distance from metropolitan centers (differentiated by size) ranges from high relative importance to low relative importance in determining fertility levels within both residence groups. Agricultural Occgpation When considering measure of all occupations, it was found that relationships obtained varied from a clear in— verse, in some cases, curvilinear or nonsignificant, to a slightly direct one. In general, it appears that measures of the complete broad occupational group distribution were relatively unimportant in accounting for variation in fer- tility, especially in urban areas. An inverse relation per— sisted in rural—farm population, especially among the two primary agricultural occupations: farmers and farm laborers. Although an inverse relation of fertility to proportions of farmers and direct relation to proportions of farm laborers should be persistent within rural areas, it is concluded they will not be as relevant in urban situations, nor will relative importance be very high. The following propositions for the agricultural occupations are extracted from the previous discussions on the occupation variable: 3. Fertility is inversely related to proportion of farmers and farm managers in the labor force within rural areas. 4. Fertility is directly related to proportion of farm laborers and farm foremen in the labor force within rural areas. 5. Fertility ranges from an inverse to a nonsignificant relation to proportion of farmers and farm managers in the labor force within the urban sector. 139 6. Fertility ranges from a direct to a nonsignificant relation to proportion of farm laborers and farm foremen in the labor force within the urban sector. 7. Agricultural occupations are of intermediate rela— tive importance in accounting for rural—farm fertil— ity variance. 8. Agricultural occupations are of low reletive impor- tance in accounting for urban fertility variance. Education Wife's educational attainment level revealed a persistently strong inverse relationship with fertility. Because wife's educational level tended to be more important than the husband's in accounting for fertility differences, couple's educational attainment level follows the wife's lead and appears, then, as a compromise level of association between the husband's and wife's educational attainment, an association still strongly inverse, but weaker than wife's education. This relationship is inverse for both residence groups and adult educational attainment is relatively impor— tant in both residence groups. A list of extracted proposi- tions follow for adult educational attainment level: 9. Fertility is inversely related to adult educational attainment level within both residence groups. 10. Adult educational attainment is of high relative -importance in determining fertility levels in all residence groups, to a degree more within rural areas, and less within urban areas. 'DA‘V ‘ ...x. . any-- on r -o; l “‘1‘.‘ 140 Income Husband's income was shown to vary from a slight inverse, sometime curvilinear or nonsignificant, to a moder— ate direct association, more so in urban areas. Family in— come revealed a more consistent inverse relation with fertil- ity, although tendencies toward a moderate direct relation is possible in urban areas. This difference is largely due to working wives. Controlling for female employment and female income would tend to reduce the importance of family income especially in urban areas. In addition, female in— come tended to exert a consistent but moderate inverse influence on fertility in both residence groups. Its rela— tive importance is slight, but perhaps greater in urban areas contrasted with the rural. Propositions dealing with family income and female income are considered below: 11. Fertility is inversely related to family income within the rural population. 12. Fertility ranges from a slight inverse, perhaps non— significant, to a moderate positive relation to family income with the urban population. 13. Family income is of intermediate relative importance in accounting for fertility variance within both residence groups, of possibly higher importance within urban areas. 14. Fertility is inversely related to female income within the urban population. 15. Fertility ranges from a slightly inverse to a non- significant relation to female income within rural areas. 16. Female income is of intermediate relative importance in determining urban fertility. 141 17. Female income is of low relative importance in determining rural fertility. Female Employment A measure recognizing all women in the labor force, regardless of marital status, is a weaker factor than ever— married women in the labor force, but an inverse relation is nevertheless expected. Female employment accounts for a greater portion of fertility variations in urban areas than the rural. Extracted propositions for proportions of women employed in the labor force are presented as follows: 18. Fertility is inversely related to females employed in the labor force in urban areas. 19. Fertility ranges from an inverse to a nonsignificant relation to female employment within the rural popu- lation. 20. Female employment is of intermediate relative impor— tance in accounting for urban fertility variance. 21. Female employment is of low relative importance in accounting for rural fertility variance. Age Composition Relative concentration of women of the child-bearing ages in the early segment of this span is much more important irnpredicting fertility levels than relative concentration in tine later segments. A strong inverse association obtains for Preportion of young women of childbearing age in both resi- dence groups because of fluctuations in age of marriage in this period. Proportions of intermediate aged women in the childbearing age group varies from a possible slight inverse, in some cases nonsignificant, to a slight direct relation 142 with fertility. Fluctuations in fertility level off sharply among this group, but the tendency for urban women to delay marriage suggests the possibility of this factor being slightly more important within the urban population. Prop— ositions for these two factors are suggested as follows: 22. Fertility is inversely related to proportion of young women of childbearing age within both resi- dence groups. 23. Proportion of young women of childbearing age is of intermediate relative importance in accounting for fertility variance within both residence groups. 24. Fertility ranges from a slight inverse, at times nonsignificant, to a slight direct relation to proportions of intermediate aged women of childbear— ing age within the urban population. 25. Fertility ranges from a nonsignificant to a slightly direct relation to proportion of intermediate aged women of childbearing age within the rural popula- tion. 26. Proportion of intermediate aged women of childbear— ing age is of low relative importance in both resi— dence groups, although slightly higher for the urban population. Conclusion Table 15 provides a tabular summary of the expected results of an analysis of residential fertility variations (both expected direction of association and expected rela— ‘tive importance of the independent variable in accounting ifor variation within residential fertility) based upon the empirical propositions which have been constructed from the intensive review of thirty—one selected empirical studies. This table, it must be recalled, is not the product of 143 .mmmmcpcmumm CH pwmoaocm uoc mmOQu mm Hoooo on mamxfla mm uoc mum nofln3 mmflcmcowumamu pmpommxm mmocu muocmo A V mommcucmummt uomuao A.m.zv Auomuflov moms mcwummnpaflno CH canon 30d Ammum>ch 3oq .m.z cmEo3 pmmm mumaomfinmucH .m mmmm mcflummn omcflaumumocb mumeomaumucH mmum>cH mumopmaumucH mmum>cH Itaono CH cwEoB mcoow .m .m.z chHD mumnomauoucH mmum>cH 30g Ammnm>ch ucmfimoamfim mHmEmm .h .m.z chHD mumflomfiumucH mmum>cH 30A Ammum>ch mEoocH mamfimm .o uomnno roam 0n A.m.zv chHD mumoooaumucH Ammum>ch muMflomEHmucH mmum>cH mEoocH haflfimm .m Hmuom roam mmum>cH roam mmum>cH coaumuoom paste .e .m.z Hmuom 3oq Anomuoov muMHomEumucH uomuflo smEmHom o mumuonmq Eumm .m ImOZ Hmuom 304 Ammum>ch mumflpmaumucH mmum>cH mummmcmz Eumm o mHmEHmm .N “.m.zv *A.m.zv AmNHm mnv Hmucmo cmufl pmcHEumumocb scalrmfim common Boninmflm uomuflo Iaooouuwe Eonm mocmumao .H mocmuHomEH mocmuuomEH coauomnfla mocmunomEH coauomnflm mmHQMflHm> ucmpcwmwocH m>HumHmm m>numawm mwnmcowumamm m>HumHmm QHSmCOAumamm “mamas nuns mocmoflmmm canon Hmuom muHHHuHmw mGHcHEHmumU CH mmaflmaum> ucmpcmmmocfi mo mocmuuomfifl m>flumamu pmuowm mmHQMHHm> ucmflcwmmficfl Umuomamm 0U muflafluumw MO mmHSmGOflumamH Umuommxw wvcwfiflmwu UGm mHQMHHm> ucmwcmmmwcfl ND mQOHUHmomOHQ HMUHHflmEm m0 NHMEEdw HmHSQmB monoum wocmoflmmn can: cod .umwnm> No new «WhomquU J ‘I ‘q An; I4: 144 theoretical considerations but of the consistency of find— ings from previous empirical studies. On the basis of what other researchers have found regarding differential fertil- ity patterns within residence categories, then, these are the empirical relationships which one might expect to obtain in a study similar to the present one. We may employ this summary table to reconsider some of the ideas presented in the previous chapter concerning urban and rural differential fertility patterns. Recall it was suggested that there might be discovered different pat- terns of differential fertility in each of the residence categories, thus, justifying the investigation of urban and rural populations separately. Table 15 indicates that we should expect some differences between residential catego- ries, but these differences may not be extreme. This may be due to the difficulty of summarizing the findings of such diverse studies and/or the inability to differentiate finer distinctions with the categories employed, i.e., the use of "inverse" or "direct" to describe the direction of expected association and the terms "low," "intermediate," and "high" tO indicate relative importance. Generally the independent Variables which are expected to be most important in deter— minixug residential fertility reveal similar patterns in.both reSindence groups, e.g., education, distance from metropolitan Cent er, and proportion of young women in childbearing ages. Differences in patterns of relationship and relative impor— tance are greater for independent variables which are .. -1 bu .- in m ’1 145 expected to reveal inconsistent, fluctuating relationships and are expected to have less influence in determining res- idential fertility, e.g., agricultural occupation, female income and female employment. Slight differences in direc- tion of association with fertility are expected for six of the nine independent variables: agricultural occupations, family income, female income, female employment, and propor- tions of intermediate aged women in childbearing ages. The greater contrast in considering differential fertility pat— terns by residence seems to be for the relative importance of independent variables in accounting for fertility varia— tion. This might suggest the possibility that, while the direction of association between fertility and related inde— pendent variables may actually remain the same within resi— dence categories, the same independent variable may have a different impact on fertility in rural areas than in urban areas. This would still support the original hypothesis of contrasting differential fertility patterns within residence groups. A distinction between rural—farm and rural—nonfarm fertility has not been established in Table 15. There did not appear enough evidence in the empirical studies reviewed todifferentiate clearly enough the differential fertility Pattxarns which one might expect in each of these populations. Shmilar to the discussion of Chapter I, we have treated "rurzflfl as one category. Though it was impossible to con— Struct empirical propositions for these two subcomponents 146 of the rural population, i.e., farm and nonfarm, it is expected that the rural—nonfarm fertility patterns will fall somewhere between the urban and rural-farm patterns, perhaps more approximating the rural-farm than the urban. In the major analysis of this thesis, all three residence categories will be considered. Hence, in terms of expected relationships, we would maintain that the patterns for the rural population as described in Table 15 would apply equally to the rural-farm and rural-nonfarm populations. But the most important function this summary table of empirical propositions will perform in this study is as a guideline for direction in theoretical considerations. One could simply test these empirical propositions as presented, but what gain would this be considering the amoung of empir- ical descriptive documentation that has already been com- piled? What theoretical contribution would this make to the explanation of differential fertility patterns? The inten- tion in the next chapter is to review some theoretical frame works relevant to the explanation of residential differen- tial fertility, but then to use these empirical propositions t0 determine which theoretical framework has the greater Prdbability of successfully predicting residential fertility Pattuerns. This, it seems to me, is the proper use of past reseearch findings. This is the method by which a science Imnmes most efficiently from a descriptive to an explanatory leve: 1 . u... 5,. -... v- I H, CHAPTER III THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FOR STUDY OF DIFFERENTIAL FERTILITY In view of the fact that this study is primarily demographic in nature, this particular chapter dealing with a theoretical framework for the study of differential fer— tility has proven the most difficult to construct. One of the chief intentions of this thesis is to meet "head—on" some of the many criticisms which have been tossed at dif— ferential fertility investigations based on census data and to correct in the design of this study for the glaring defi— ciencies of past studies. Mention has been made in Chapter I of some of these criticisms and corrections have been pro— posed. However, those mentioned previously are primarily methodological. To be comprehensive and consistent, atten— tion must now be focused toward solving theoretical criti- cisms and deficiencies. Indeed, it is a temptation to sim- Ply proceed to test the empirical propositions abstracted from relevant literature, a procedure which is normative for research in this area. However, it is felt working from a theoretical framework, however formidable and unwelcome the task, is necessary if this area of demographic research is tetuantinue to make advances. Vance makes a more dramatic 147 148 emphasis when he says, "Empirical operations without basic theory, no matter how carefully safeguarded, are now proved dangerous." The procedure for this chapter is, first, to con— sider the status of differential fertility theory (and popu- lation theory in general); second, to suggest critical guide— lines for theoretical design which will correct for past weaknesses and deficiencies in the study of differential fertility; and, third, to construct a theoretical framework which can be used to provide adequate explanation of the patterns found in the empirical data of this study as well as can be considered a solid contribution to demographic theory, and, more specifically, differential fertility theory. Status of Differential FertilityiTheogy It is precisely the status of differential fertility theory, and for that matter population theory in general, that makes the inclusion of a chapter on theoretical frame— Mmrk in a demographic study so absurd. For, according to the experts, the keystone characteristic of this field and, hence, the most devastating criticism, is the lack of theory in demography and the paucity of theoretical activity pro— duCed by demographers. lRupert Vance, "Is Theory for Demographers?" Social Ehorces, XXXI (1952), 13. 149 It was this situation which lead Vance to entitle his disturbing article "Is Theory for Demographers?" His answer to this question, of course, is affirmative, but his description of demographic theory it as a "wasteland."2 Others have made exactly the same claim. Hauser asserts, "there is still too much of a tendency among population stu- dents to produce discrete, descriptive studies with little or no attention to theoretical framework as a basis for their research orientation or for the formulation of their conclusions."3 Moore also makes note of this fact in com- paring sociology and demography. If a standard complaint about sociology is that is has "too much? theory, a standard complaint about demography is that is has "too little." . . . What is generally meant in the case of demography is that a pervasive pre— occupation with refinement of measurement and with is hoc explanations for observations leads to an avoidance of the fundamental question, what do we want to know? Of special interest to this study is that in this same chap— ter Moore cites "the preoccupation of many demographers with the analysis of census data" as a partial foundation for the exaggerated charge that demography has "no" or "too little" theory, and in the same breath he asserts "the absence of 21bid. 3Philip Hauser, "Present Status and Prospects of Research in Population," American Sociological Review, XIII (August, 1948), 377. 4Wilbert E. Moore, "Sociology and Demography," in E>, Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Population (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1959), p. 845. ‘ Aa‘ .... I.— o.» I-~. |i~. 150 any clear—cut theory of fertility differentials."5 Though all sorts of answers have been presented in response to the charge that there is a dearth of demographic theory, one fact is sure, that there is a predominant tendency for demog— raphers to prefer a raw empirical approach vis—a—vis a Eheof retically sophisticated approach in demographic research. The result is, as Davis states, "the tendency to initiate research either with no explicit hypotheses at all or with hypotheses pulled out of a hat."6 Hence, regardless of the excuses put forth to explain the situation, it is true that differential fertility theory, and demographic theory in general, is "poverty stricken." Critical Guidelines for a Theoretical Design for the Study of Differential Fertiligy In response to this general charge against demo- graphic theory, however, several demographers have proposed constructive points which could strengthen the theoretical condition of demography if effectively incorporated into basic research. There are a select number of such points Vflhich I wish to call upon for the purpose of providing "crit- irzal guidelines" for a theoretical design. There are four altogether . 5Ibid., p. 849. 6Kingsley Davis, "The Sociology of Demographic Behavior," in R. K. Merton, L. Broom, and L. Cottrell, Socnxology Today (New YOrk: Basic Books, 1959), p. 323. ..7\.. 151 The first guideline flows from a criticism leveled at demographic studies that the "explanatory" function of theory has been neglected. After reviewing several examples of what demographers consider "theory," Hauser and Duncan make this their first "critical observation.” . . . there is relatively little emphasis in the state— ments of demographers on the explanatory_snd predictive functions of theogy. At least in the opinion of many writers on scientific method, what distinguishes proposi- tions of a "theoretical" character from mere empirical generalizations is that the former state considerations as a consequence of which certain empirical regularities are expected to obtain and indicate conditions under which such regularities will hold, i.e., theories are supposed to "explain" and "predict" the facts at the command of a discipline. . . . If this crucial feature of scientific theory is neglected, it becomes possible to accept as "theories" various bodies of discourse which incorporate several of the ingredients of theory (such as concepts, definitions, and deductions) but which fail tp_perform theipringipal function of theopy. Later in the same chapter Hauser and Duncan seem to provide a plausible explanation as to why demographers have neglected this function of theory. In a critical comment on "psycho— social theories of fertility" (primary reference is to the Indianapolis Study) they make the statement that: it may be, too, that they have hit on an issue of signal importance for population studies in general in stating an antithesis between testing a particular theory and the_prediction of a concrete event. If, like most demog- raphers, they prefer to attempt the prediction or expla— nation of concrete events, they seem prepared to sacri- fice some of the elegance of an integrated theory. 7Philip Hauser and Otis Dudley Duncan, The Study of Population (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1957), pp. 84-5 (italics mine). 8Ibid., p. 97. 152 Hence, theory development has been sacrificed for the narrow conception that the primary objective of any scientific research is the mere prediction of a concrete event. In View of such an objective, of course, the most appropriate and efficient research design is the "dragnet" approach (a continuous accumulation of independent variables until the dependent variable is satisfactorily "explained" to the neglect of any understanding of how all the employed vari— ables fit together in an integrated, logical fashion). All too often it is this approach which has been found popular in past differential fertility studies. This must be altered. To correct for past deficiencies, therefore, the first critical guideline requires that the "explanatory" function of theory be the foremost consideration in theory construction and that the nature of the problem contained in this thesis be discerned as "theory testing" rather than merely "predicting a concrete event." To follow this guide- line, of course, is not going to be without its casualties. Vance skillfully describes the risks involved, but also the challenge: If there is room in demography for the timid souls, is there also room for the bold and audacious? In science as in poker, we realize we can play it one of two ways. We can play it close to the vest, that is, maximize description and minimize synthesis or we can play it for maximum gains of human knowledge. . . . Accordingly the closer one sticks to his data, the less vulnerable are his generalizations and ofttimes the less important. A loose thoughtsystem sacrifices accuracy for the sake of generalization. 153 In science when one plays for double or nothing, he runs the risk of evolving a system of high generaliza- tions and low validity. Obviously this represents high vulnerability and we are all cautious enough to dread the results. But we should remember there are two forms of maximum error: the first is a system that misses con— tact with the known facts at every point of observation. The second is no system at all. This is maximum error, for it equates with total ignorance. As a matter of fact, I am willing to make the claim that he who devel— ops a theory capable of being proved invalid makes a contribution. In statistics the disproof of any hypoth— esis is accepted as a way station on the road to knowl— edge. Demographers should become brave enough to so state their hypotheses that they are capable of dis— proof. The second critical guideline follows from the crit— icism that demographers have maintained a limited conception of what constitutes the essential ingredients of theory and that demographers have not made full use of all these levels of ingredients. This criticism is not difficult to substan- tiate. Hauser and Duncan suggest this in making the follow- ing critical observation of demographic theory: It is not evident in the cited writings of demog— raphers that "theories" may be stated at widely varying levels of generality and with greater or lesser scope of applicability. It is possible that some of the concern over lack of theory in population studies reflects a failure to recognize that the functions of theory can be performed at different levels of specificity and that each level is potentially significant for some purposes. As one might expect there exists the eternal ques- tion of what are the essential ingredients of theory? Though disagreement would be forthcoming upon whatever one 9Rupert B. Vance, op. cit., p. 12. 10Philip Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 85. 10 154 proposed as the "essential” ingredients, there is sufficient consensus concerning this question which will permit the assertion of a significant observation about demographic theory. For example, Gutman notes that while there is con- fusion in the meaning of the word "theory," in practice "generalizations on several different levels of abstraction with varying degrees of comprehensiveness are labeled popu— lation theory."ll Though this list is not exhaustive, some of the ingredients of theory suggested by Gutman are "con- cepts,"12 "general orientations toward substantive mate- rials,"13 "empirical generalizations,"14 and "societal llRobert Gutman, "In Defense of Population Theory," American Sociological Review, XXV (June, 1960), 329. 12Gutman writes: "The term 'theory' has been used as a synonym for a great number of concepts used to organize population data. The task of analyzing the assumptions and implications of these concepts, and refining them, has been considered a kind of theoretical activity." Ibid., p. 329. l3Gutman uses Robert Merton's phrase to describe this ingredient: "Such orientations involve broad postulates which indicate types of variables which are somehow to be taken into account rather than specifying determinate rela— tionships between particular variables." Ibid., p. 331. 14Of these Gutman writes: "Several theoretical key- stones of contemporary population study are really empirical generalizations; that is to say, they describe 'a set of uniform conjunctions of traits repeatedly observed to exist, without any understanding of phy the conjunction occurs; without a theory which states its rationale.I Transition theory and goneralizations about the inverse relationship_ between fertility and socio-economic status probabiy belong_ in this category) even though demographers do have positive notions about why the demographic transition has taken place and the reasons which explain the higher fertility among the poor. But they are notions rather than carefully conceived and well-reasoned explanations." Ibid, p. 331 (italics mine). 155 laws."15 Hauser and Duncan earlier attempted to synthesize selected demographic materials and concluded that the ingre— dients of theory according to demographers include: (a) concepts defined within a frame of reference; (b) empirical propositions, generalizations, or laws (which vary in generality and “ credibility); (c) prop- ositions, hypotheses, or theorems deduced or constructed from other elements of theory, with these taking the form of (d) "necessary relations," "models" incorporat- ing necessary and/or empirical relations, or "purely hypothetical constructions." Although Gutman makes a strong case that demograph- ers have contributed more in the way of theory construction at the several levels of theory ingredients than what others are willing to credit them, he does not suggest the quite realistic possibility that demographers' contribution to theory—building has been to a large extent concentrated in the area of "empirical generalizations" (to use Gutman's phrase). Hence, while demographers should be commended for not entirely neglecting theory development in their disci— pline, it must be emphasized that any mass production of empirical propositions alone is not a sound approach to theory development. In such a case there is still too much wanting. Attempts to clearly spell out the variety of ingredients which constitute theory are intended to influence 15According to Gutman "societal laws differ from empirical generalizations because they are derived from statements on a higher level of abstraction, and are the product of deduction rather than induction." Ibid., p. 332. l6Philip Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 84. 156 the initiation of theoretical activity at many levels, not to encourage specialization tendencies in selected direc- tions. In practice, then, demographers have not met this theoretical need. As a result, and Gutman himself suggests this, the theoretical contributions of differential fertility studies employing socio-economic status variables fall mostly under the rubric of "empirical generalizations." But there is more to "theory" than just "empirical generalizations." Dinkel clearly reveals the inadequacies of such an approach in his criticism of a fertility study which he described as "another inheritor of the Indianapolis Study legacy." Dinkel writes: Even if correlations of high order were found and theoretical inconsistencies between supported and unsup- ported hypotheses were ironed out, the authors still would have the task of explaining the processes by which operation of the model yielded the correlations. Corre- lations need to be buttressed by_qgalitative materials and logical connections that indicate the processes through which the independent variables are associated with fertilipy. Physical scientists are more accustomed than social scientists to so finishing the job of research and not letting it stop with the obtaining of statistical asso— ciation between the variables. In the physical sciences, of course, possession of more closely—reasoned theoreti— cal models that are supported by much past research of an additive character makes more possible the crucial experiment from which results can be taken directly and fed back into the analytical structure; in other words, the explanation of quantitative associations found in the test are at hand before the test is made. In the social sciences, on the other hand, it is necessary to backtrack from the correlations to other research and to ~e 157 the conceptual framework in order to juggle the_pieces together in a new whole.17 It is strongly felt that criticism such as this must not be written off as only an "interesting comment" which might be wisely considered by the designers of that partic— ular study, but it can be legitimately and accurately ex— tended to all demographic investigations which seem to proudly hail as their ultimate objective the empirical sub— stantiation of a battery of disconnected hypotheses, implic- itly or explicitly stated, which leads to the careless stock- piling of irrelevant empirical propositions. On the other hand, it must be noted that deploring this tendency in demo— graphic studies does not in any fashion give full blessing to the type of "theorizing" which produces abstract proposi- tions which are finally systematically and logically related but which have no empirical referents. We must concur with Davis when, in condemning this trend in the social sciences, he acclaims: In social science this term (theory), instead of meaning the widest body of rigorous reasoning about a set of observed relationships, has come to mean a long stretch of purely verbal analysis. If a publication contains any empirical evidence, particularly of a statistical kind, it is not theory; but if it contains only verbal generalizations, no matter how loosely connected, it is theory. 8 17Robert M. Dinkel, "Fertility in Mid-Century America," Eugenics Quarterly, III (March, 1956), 26 (italics mine). l8Kingsley Davis, "The Sociology of Demographic Behavior," op. cit., p. 313. -n .5 "1 .n A». -.. ...“ a...‘ o ‘I-‘ “l‘ ~ 5‘.‘ u ‘- 158 There is an all too obvious solution by which the making of obeisance to either undesirable form of theoretical activity mentioned above can be avoided, and this introduces the statement of the second critical guideline for the theo- retical design of this study. A reasonably sound approach to theory-building is the unending attempt to integrate all levels of theory ingredients into the same theoretical frame— work, especially empirically produced and theoretically deduced propositions. Hence, theorizing must take the form of bridging the gap between empirical propositions and theo— retical hypotheses, of employing to the fullest extent pos— sible all empirical propositions which have been established and all theoretical frameworks which are relevant. obviously this guideline is not original, but it is felt the explicit statement of this research ideal will go far in correcting for mistakes made in past differential fertility studies. The third critical guideline for the theoretical design of this study takes its cue from a plea by a number of demographers for the development of "theories of the middle range." In Robert Merton's own words, such theories are those "intermediate to the minor working hypotheses evolved in abundance during the day by day routines of research, and the all—inclusive speculations comprising a master conceptual scheme from which it is hoped to derive a very large number of empirically observed uniformities of 159 social behavior."19 In the eyes of these demographers "theories of the middle range" are viewed as the best and only answer to resolving the dearth—of—demographic—theory problem. Furthermore, it is speculated that in no other area of the social sciences than demography is the theoret— ical void at this level so noticeable and obstructive to the advancement of the discipline. Hillery perceives a critical lacking of middle range theory in both sociology and demography, but foresees this type of theory as a significant key to the integration of both fields.20 Like Hillery, Vance also makes a firm appeal for making middle range theorizing fashionable. Vance's hope expressed in his article was that a whole new era of demographic theory would now be possible because of this new directive. This means that demographic theory would now be constructed at a level that would permit a procedure of test— ing, disproving and refining. Now it would be possible to correct for another major deficiency of past population theories (to put it in the words of Hauser and Duncan): . . . that they are stated so generally or abstractly that they fail to "make contact" with the facts or with regularities which have thus far been established empir- ically or, what comes down to the same thing, that their 19Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social Struc- ture (Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1957), p. 9. 20George Hillery, Jr., "Toward a Conceptualization of Demography," Social Forces, XXXVII (October, 1958), 49-51. 0! .s \u I'. g i. 9., '\ ‘A‘. '5‘: N-~ a ll' 4. Ill 160 predictions are of such a general character that they are not readily refuted or confirmed by evidence now available or likely soon to become available.21 This is, indeed, a quite opposite criticism posited against demographic theory when the discussion of the second criti— cal guideline presented above is considered. Both criti- cisms are valid, nevertheless, as Vance indicates in his article. Demographic theory has been guilty of "theorizing" too close to empirical data as well as "theorizing" out of contact with empirical data. Middle range theory is pre— cisely what is needed to bridge the gap. Though several years have passed since Vance wrote his article, the fact that his prediction that "when all the hypotheses of the Indianapolis Study are finally fused, popu- lation will have a healthy young theory of the middle range"22 did not come true is perhaps indicative of the snail's pace at which demography has attempted to rise to Vance's request for the development of middle range theory. Nevertheless there are "sproutings" of middle range theory which are now developing in demographic fertility analysis and one shall have to consider these in any attempt to bring theory into contact with empirical data. Finally the fourth critical guideline which will influence the theoretical design of this thesis is easier to 21Philip Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 85. 22Rupert Vance, op. cit., p. 90. 161 spell out than to operationalize. Mention was made above concerning the recent emergence of some middle range theo— ries dealing with differential fertility. In one sense this is exactly what Dr. Vance had ordered, but from another point of View this places the researcher in direct confronta- tion with the sticky problem of choosing which middle range theoretical framework to employ in fertility research. The fact that none of these theories are what one might call "full—grown" theories, since all of them contain the usual gaps and lack repeated empirical substantiation, adds to the dilemmatic nature of the choice. This "pieces and patches" condition of fertility theory is perhaps the underlying rea— son why, quite subsequent to the classic Indianapolis Study, investigators have repeatedly rejected the scheme of select- ing a particular theory to direct fertility analysis. Mishler and Westoff, principal investigators for the Prince- ton Study, reasoned that developing a particular theory is unwise because there are "insufficient grounds for selecting any particular 'theory' which would automatically restrict the types and ranges of data gathered."23 The question can be raised, however, as to whether this was the only and wisest choice in the light of the status of fertility theory. 23Elliot Mishler and Charles Westoff, "A Proposal for Research on Social Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility: Concepts and Hypotheses," in Current Research in Human Fertility (New YOrk: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1955), p. 128. 162 Their choice was one of “no theory" or the hope that a uni- fied theory would evolve from their efforts, as Hauser and Duncan describe this procedure: What the investigators do propose to use is a "concep— tual framework or 'model' which (permits) the descrip— tion of the major elements of the concrete situation within which the fertility event takes place." As expounded, this "conceptual framework" appears to amount to an a priori classification of "dependent variables" and "independent variables," whose use "entails a cer- tain risk that the hypotheses which are formulated will form together less of a unified whole than would be the case if the study were developed in terms of a single body of theory." 4 Ignoring existing theory is herewith rejected as an acceptable procedure for the present study. To make use of existing theory, however, considering the current status of fertility theory, it is felt that some rather untried pro- cedure must be adopted. Casting about for instances of such a procedure, I find that Westie25 most closely approaches the model in mind. Although "Westie's procedure" will not be replicated, the "spirit" of what is called for in this fourth critical guideline is captured in his introductory comments to his suggested procedure. He proposes the util- ization of his procedure in areas of investigation where there exists "a high degree of theoretical incoherence," where "knowledge consists of numerous contradictory theories 24Philip Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 97. 25Frank R. Westie, "Toward Closer Relations Between Theory and Research: A Procedure and an Example," American Sociological Review, XXII (April, 1957), 149-54. 163 and fragments of theories that have been constructed to explain 'empirical relationships,‘ which may or may not exist."26 His procedure is described as an alternative to procedures the researcher more customarily follows under "incoherent" theoretical conditions, such as: 1. He resorts to a rigid empiricism in which the "facts" (meaning the empirical findings) are seen to speak for themselves. . . . 2. He selects from among the many contradictory propositions already held in the field a particular proposition or set of propositions which are relevant to the problem at hand and which appear to make sense in terms of what the investigator already knows about the aspect of society under investigation. 27 3. He creates a new set of propositions of his own. Briefly his procedure proposes the utilization of all the theoretical propositions in the area of investigation as they exist, with all their contradictions and inadequacies. It involves "listing a comprehensive range of presupposed empirical relationships . . . which might possibly turn up in the research at hand and explicitly listing a range of interpretations . . . for each possible empirical finding." The relationships that are supported by empirical investiga- tion are retained and the correct theoretical interpreta— tions are selected from the array of contradictory though "plausible" interpretations attached to the empirical rela- tionships that have survived the research test. 26Ibid., p. 149. 27Ibid. 164 It is not my intention to follow this procedure wholly, but Westie's suggestion that we begin testing con— tradictory theories and hypotheses against each other is promising for differential fertility analysis, given its current status and deficiencies. To meet this critical guideline I intend to consider two theoretical frameworks which have been employed in differential fertility analysis but which lead to contrasting hypotheses. These two theoret— ical frameworks are "urban dominance" theory (presently in- corporated in the logical extensions of demographic transi— tion theory) and "metropolitan dominance" theory. Empirical propositions have already been established by which to deter- mine which of these frameworks leads to the more valid con— clusions. In this manner Westie's suggestions (making up the fourth critical guideline) will be implemented. However, this procedure will also, I claim, face up to the other three critical guidelines established above. I consider both theories to be of the middle range variety. Further- more, the design of this study will go far in bridging the gap between empirical propositions and theoretical hypoth— eses. All levels of theory ingredients will be employed. .Finally, the explanatory function of theory is especially emphasized in this manner over against a narrow concern for Preediction of concrete events. Let us now turn to implementing these guidelines. Beifore contrasting the two theoretical frameworks and 165 generating hypotheses, however, an introduction to the implications of a distributive design for the theoretical framework is necessary. Theoretical Framework It has been stated in a previous discussion of the research design of this study that the distributive approach is to be employed to investigate comparatively variation in rural and urban fertility. This approach necessitates the study of a given population in terms of spatial patterns among designated areal subdivisions of its territory. Anal- ysis involves the discovery of population characteristics of these areal units which covary with population characteris— tics of these same units. Explanation rather than descrip- tion should be the objective of the distributive approach, but the discovery of a statistical relationship or the uncov— ering of factors that are nonrandomly related to population events cannot be interpreted as being causal. The distribu- tive approach is only a particular type of research design, not a theoretical framework. Cause must be inferred from theoretical considerations. Hence, at this juncture a theo— retical framework should be selected to complement the dis- tr‘:i‘butive approach as a basic research design of this study. From the point of view of this study, an ecological fréamework is best suited to a situation wherein the distribu- titre approach is employed and provides the best means for U. ‘F. p '\ . u. -" ‘v ”o (" I 1,, h‘~ v“. .t‘ 166 ordering demographic data intelligibly. Noting that human ecology focuses on the impact of man's environment on human behavior, Bogue himself infers an ecological framework when he states that "population distribution studies are capable of contributing a great deal of indirect information about environmental factors that underlie population events."28 The unit of analysis for human ecologists, however, is not merely a population aggregate, but a human population more or less circumscribed territorially. Though the community is not the only ecological unit of analysis that fits this description, it certainly has been a most frequently chosen unit of analysis in ecological research. Hawley himself, a leading contributor to ecological theory, argued that a community is "the basic unit of ecological investigation,29 though others have questioned the expediency of this asser— tion.3O Nevertheless, from an ecological point of View the community definitely maintains a territorial dimension, as Suggested by Duncan and Reiss' definition of community: "The territorially oriented complex of human relationships through which a more or less ecological population meets its 28Donald J. Bogue, "Population Distribution," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 393. 29Amos Hawley, Human Ecology (New York: The Ronald Press, 1950), p. 180. 30O. D. Duncan, "Human Ecology and Population Studies," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, op. cit., p. 684. b.- ' I.” ...n 5') I V‘a. v . ‘- ,— 'V‘v. .- ‘I‘. . a. b..- u. p. I “v.. 167 sustenance and residence requirements."31 The unit of analysis for this study, as reported previously, is the residential part of a county and is to be considered an approximation of the ecological definition of community. Given the community as the unit of analysis, the next logical consideration is inter—community variation. That communities vary one from another, even in the same geographical region, is common sense, but why communities vary must be answered by a theoretical framework, specifi- cally ecological. When ecologists speak of community varia- tion, they speak in terms of structural differentiation, variations in social structure or social organization. The social organization or structure of a community is viewed by ecologists as "a collective adaptation on the part of a population to its total environment (including other orga- nized populations, as well as physical features), an adapta- tion that is strongly modified by the technological equip- ment in use and by certain 'purely' demographic attributes Of the population itself, notably its size, rate of growth, and biological (age—sex) composition."32 In this View of <20mmunity social organization one can readily identify the four main referential concepts which human ecology embraces: 31O. D. Duncan and A. J. Reiss, Jr., Social Charac- teristics of Urban and Rural Communities, 1950 (New York: John Wiley, 1956), p. xiii. 32L€0 Schnore, "Social Morphology and Human Ecology," Aperican Journal of SociologY, LXIII (May, 1958), 629. 168 population, environment, technology, and (social) organiza— tion. These are referred to collectively as the "ecological complex" or the "ecosystem."33 To understand variation in community social organization or social structure, then, one must perceive it as a product or outcome of the unique demo— graphic, technological, and environmental pressures which the community confronts, though one must not discount the interdependent relationship of the elements of the ecolog— ical complex and the reciprocal effects which social organi— zation may bring to bear on the other elements. Community variation is not random or unexplicable, therefore, but reflects the operation of unique combinations of local conditions. The dependent variable of this study, however, is not social organization but a population event, namely, fer— tility. In the same manner that we may consider social orga— nization as a collective adaptation to unique demographic, technological, and environmental pressures which a community Confronts, we may also view fertility, being a component Of population growth, as a collective adaptation of a com- ITl‘unity to the influences of its peculiar organizational, 33O. D. Duncan, "Human Ecology and Population S‘tudies," op. cit., pp. 681-84; Leo Schnore, op. cit., I). 629; O. D. Duncan and Leo Schnore, "Cultural, Behavioral Eand Ecological Perspectives in the Study of Social Organiza- tion," American Journal of Sociology, XLV (September, 1959), 135-6; and O. D. Duncan, "From Social System to Ecosystem," §£§iological Inguigy, XXXI (Spring, 1961), 140-9. 169 technological, and environmental (including other organized populations) conditions. Duncan himself suggests that one of the distinctively ecological contributions to the study of the vital processes (fertility and mortality) is the study of "vital rates as indexes of the adjustment of a population to its environment and investigation of the impact of variations in community structure and function on the vital processes."34 It is hypothesized, then, on the basis of an ecolog— ical framework, that community social structure or organiza— tion will play a significantly determinative role in fertil- ity variation among communities. Discussions on the distrib- utive design, human ecology and demography point to popula- tion composition as an excellent source for operationalizing indices of community social organization. Bogue asserts that the "study of how differential population composition leads to differential population behavior (in our case, fertility behavior) is one of two major aspects of distri- butional analysis."35 Duncan states that "the principal interests of the human ecologist in the study of population <30mposition are the exploitation of data on composition as 34O. D. Duncan, "Human Ecology and Population Studies," op. cit., p. 698. 5 Donald J. Bogue, "Population Distribution," .Op. cit., p. 384. 170 indicators of ecological organization."36 Likewise, Schnore maintains that "a compositional View of population inevitably provides a proximate description of social structure. . . ."37 Hence population composition indices operationalized on an areal basis at the community level reflect community social structure and may be expected to significantly influence fertility behavior. In commenting on aggregate social data for areal units as indices of social structure, Feldman and Tilly argue that . . . the residential area is one important context within which personal behavior takes place. Thus, the fact of living in an area with certain characteristics in income, education, race, and so on (in other words, various aspects of population composition), is sociolog- ically relevant, whether or not the personal traits of residents are similar to the averages of the areal units in which they reside. Hence residential area is a significant context in which human behavior takes place. The importance of spatial rela- tionships in ecological analysis is expressed by Duncan in three points: First, territoriality is a major factor giving unit char- acter to populations. Second, space is simultaneously a 36O. D. Duncan, "Human Ecology and Population S”Cudies," op. cit., p. 693. 37Leo F. Schnore, "Social Mobility in Demographic IPerspective," American Sociological Review, XXVI, No. 3 (June, 1961), 411. 38Arnold S. Feldman and Charles Tilly, "The Interac- tion of Social and Physical Space," American Sociological 'Review, XXV, No. 6 (December, 1960), 879. Statement in ‘Darentheses mine. For related comments on ecological corre— lation see pp. 69-72 of this thesis. .A‘I ‘3': mm. . .'A4 'uv. - ~V-u ~.. (I) 171 requisite for the activities of any organizational unit and an obstacle which must be overcome in establishing interunit relationships. Finally, space--like time-- furnishes a convenient and invariant set of reference points for observation, and observed spatio-temporal regularities and rhythms furnish convenient indicators of structural relationships. The conclusion from an ecological perspective is that fertility behavior, operationalized on a residential area basis, is a function of residential community social structure, operationalized in terms of various indices of population composition, as well as technological, environ- mental, and other demographic variables. For this study these independent variables include such indices as distance from a metropolitan center, employment in agricultural occu— pations, education, family income, female income and employ— ment, and the age structure of women in the reproductive age period.4O 39O. D. Duncan and Leo F. Schnore, "Cultural, Behavioral, and Ecological Perspectives in the Study of Social Organization," op. cit., p. 136. 40It is difficult to classify these independent Variables in terms of the four broad categories of the eco- logical complex, i.e., population, environmental, technolog- ical, and organizational, since several of these could fall -into more than one category. To facilitate the discussion :l:‘dingly populations manifest characteristic types of population growth dependent upon their stage of urbanization. Hence populations which are highly urbanized have low fertil— ity and mortality rates; populations beginning the process of urbanization portray rapidly declining mortality rates \ Am 48A. J. Jaffe, "Urbanization and Fertility, " fiiaan Journal of Sociology, .XLVIII (July, ls4z), 48-60; d Warren C. Robinson, "Urbanization and Fertility: The an‘Western Experience," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, 31. No. 3. (July, 1963), 291-308. 177 but relatively high fertility rates; populations which have not begun the transition reveal both high fertility and high mortality levels. Transition theory is traditionally extended to explain the phenomenon of the inverse fertility differentials found among the socio—economic and residential groups of populations undergoing and having undergone the transitional phase. Grabill, Kiser and Whelpton succinctly describe this process as follows: The phenomenon of differential fertility according to occupational or socio-economic status has sometimes been/ described as a transitional phase of declining fertilityfi v.4" The theory is that the decline begins in the so-called ’ "upper" occupational classes in urban areas. Later, the declines affect the so-called "middle" classes and finally the so—called "lower" occupational classes. the meantime the declines spread outward to the rural areas and presumably the process runs the same type of c ourse there . Abu—Lughod has proposed demographic transition the— In City as an analytical model which can be used to predict the \__ " 49The theory was first stated by Warren S. Thompson, 9ggptllation," American Journal of Sociology, XXXI (May, 1929), L 9~75; reformulated by Frank W. Notestein, "Population--The U21}? View," in T. w. Schultz, Food for the World (Chicago: Selversity of Chicago Press, 1945) . For other statements The : Kingsley Davis, "The World Demographic Transition," \H e Annals, CCXXXVII (January, 1945), 1-11; Kingsley Davis, fin Society (New York: Macmillan, 1949), pp. 603-8; Dennis Doohg, Population (New York: Random House, 1956); and Thnald O. Cowgill, "Transition Theory as General Population eory," Social Forces, XLI (March, 1963), 270-74. 50W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, {fiFertility of American Women (New York: John Wiley, 58), p. 180. See also D. O. Cowgill, op. cit., proposi- t J~<>ns 6 and 7, p. 273. 178 presence (or absence) of urban—rural differentials at various stages of the transition. In her introductory statement she says: Within Western industrialized countries certain dif— ferences have been noted in the demographic structures of urban and rural areas. Early in the present century, when these were first being probed, the observed varia- tions were emphasized and urban areas were considered to differ sui generis from rural ones. More recently, as urban culture has spread out from the metropolitan centers to encompass more and more of the rural hinter- lands, and as rural values, patterns, tastes, and stan- dards tend increasingly to approximate those set in cities, many of the differentials hitherto considered inviolate have begun to blur. The wide spread between 1irban and rural fertility rates commonly observed sev- eeral decades ago in the United States has been narrowing Iorecipitously, and further diminution is anticipated. True 1:raditional View of transition theory contains only three stages. Abu-Lughod proposes four phases: pre-indus— tITiiaZL, semi—industrial (early transition), industrialized (tzriarisition proper), and post-industrial society. Though SE16! (does not state it explicitly, she implies that Western colllllfl‘tries, including the United States, are moving into a rnaVV 'transition period. the "postindustrial society." During 1:}“3 transition proper period, urbanization first tends to e1"laggerate urban—rural differentials by increasing member- ssrlilp in classes likely to be experiencing fertility decline eefigggg E‘ SlJanet Abu—Lughod, "Urban—Rural Differences as a aunction of the Demographic Transition: Egyptian Data and 11 lknalytical Model," American Journal of Sociology, LXIX (March, 1964) , 476-90. 521bid., p. 476. 179 and reducing membership in classes least affected by the new fertility pattern. Hence the change in the percentage of tihe population engaged in non—agricultural pursuits results iri "an increase in the number of persons 'exposed' to condi— 53 tjxons and values favoring lowered fertility." One signif— icant change that occurs in industrial society affects the Italiationship between cities and their hinterlands. "With iruiiistrialization and more particularly with the prolifera— tiJDII of the transport and communication networks prerequi— Siilee ‘to industrial growth comes a radical expansion in the (zitzir':s sphere of influence that is manifested physically in true cievelopment of a transitional suburban ring and socio- 1-Ogi<:ally in the increased capacity of the city to affect ecCDrlcnmic conditions, aspirations, and ways of life in an 54 ever widening hinterland." Hence as city influence ex— pands, urban-rural differences in fertility contract. The everitual outcome is post—industrial society. In speaking Of this phase Abu—Lughod says: The basic characteristic of a postindustrial society is that urbanization and industrialization have become so pervasive that their presence or absence within any given geographic subarea is culturally "irrelevant." Just as preindustrial cites absorbed their dominant ethos from agrarianism, so postindustrial rural enclaves derive theirs from urbanism. In neither instance can simple criteria such as size of community, density of settlement, etc" serve as reliable indices to values or "ways of life." And just as preindustrial societies ‘-\l\_ 53Ibid., p. 488. 54Ibid., pp. 488—9. 180 maintained a relatively stable demographic balance in the absence of major urban—rural differences, the post- industrial society appears to develop its own equilib- rium despite urban—rural uniformities. One of the essential elements of transitional theory is the differential diffusion of contraceptive knowledge and use from urban to rural areas. Some historical studies of the long—term fertility decline have criticized this differ- ent ial diffusion hypothesis. They have found that there is little evidence of a delay in the reduction of rural fertil- ity compared with urban fertility. Bash provides historical evidence for the United States that indicates the secular de-‘c-'L:'Lne in birth rates was a simultaneous process for both urban and rural areas, though rural rates always appear 56 higl’ler than urban. Bash tries to explain this inconsis- tency in transition theory by disregarding social structural features of urban and rural populations. He suggests the need to think of a "dominant value orientation" or some peI‘Vading cultural factors of American society which influ— erice—ed simultaneously the secular decline of both urban and rural fertility. Bash suggests that: \ 55Ibid., p. 489. 56Wendell Bash, "Differential Fertility in Madison Ouhty, New York, 1865, " Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, 3111 (April, 1955), 161—86; Wendell Bash, "Changing Birth Ma tes in Developing America: New York State, 1840-1875," S;\lbank Memorial Fund Quarteriy, XLI (April, 1963), 161-:82. Ste also Bernard Okun, "Trends in Birth Rates in the United Hi etes since 1870, " The Johns Hopkins University Studies in refi§ytorical and Political Science, Series 76, No. 1,1958; nd W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, op. cit., 913- 16-19. r (‘1 p- 181 . . . we should study more the culture within which a particular kind of urbanism emerged. Then we might find that changes in urban and rural birth rates, rather than being responses to different cultural values, are differ- ent responses to the same ones. Efireedman, in commenting on this same finding, supplies arnother explanation based on a more structural rather than cultural analysis . The higher fertility of the rural population—-and especially the farm sector--has been well documented for a long time. Recent analyses have added the important conclusion that the long—run secular decline occurred simultaneously in both the rural and urban sectors and ‘vas not primarily a direct consequence of the transfer (of population between the sectors. Changes in the rural asector, although undoubtedly linked to changes in the lirban sector, accounted for a large part of the long—run (decline. Probabiy changes in the rural sector were pro- gguced hy its involvement in a specialized market economy ggentered in the city, It suggests that the farmer need riot go to the city to become urbanized. In various ways 1:he city can come to him. It is difficult to accept Bash's proposal of a dif— fereeritial response to the same cultural values, but the rRDtlixon of a differential response on the part of urban and ruill‘alpopulations is worth pursuing. It is puzzling as to VVrVY' the urban-rural fertility differential could not be per- <2eeifiaed as a differential response to structural factors \ 57Wendell Bash, "Changing Birth Rates in Developing flueairica: New YOrk, 1840—1875," op. cit., p. 181. 3’1. 58Ronald Freedman, "American Studies of Family I: ethning and Fertility: A Review of Major Trends and Eseyues," in C. V. Kiser, Research in Family Planning_(Prince- ju:?I1: Princeton University Press, 1962), p. 213 (italics llle). 182 rather than cultural values. However, as it has been pointed out above, the more frequent interpretation is to perceive the process of urbanization as altering rural social structure similar to urban. When social structure becomes similar for both urban and rural areas, fertility levels will converge. As Freedman has suggested, the rural sector can become urbanized without becoming part of the city because of " its involvement in a specialized market economy centered in the city." Though this conclusion is in line with urban dominance theory, it is definitely incon- gruous with metropolitan dominance theory. Metropolitan dominance theory emphasizes the notion of "specialization" or differentiation. Hence the social structures within the area of influence of a metropolitan center will tend toward s'peeCIialization, not uniformity. In contrast urban dominance t'he<:>ry hypothesizes that urbanization will affect rural Social structure similar to urban social structure. Assum- ing that fertility behavior is an adaptation to community SOC ial structure, one concludes from urban dominance theory that urban and rural fertility should eventually converge. Th3 desire of this thesis, however, is to suggest the possi— ility that urban and rural fertility are different re— Spohses to the same process, metropolitanization, not urban- i2ation. Assuming again that fertility behavior is an adeptation to community social structure, we must conclude from metropolitan dominance theory that urban and rural 183 fertility may never converge, because of the specialization effect that metropolitan centers have on the social struc- 1:ures of urban and rural communities in their sphere of iJifluence. Abu—Lughod hints at this as a possible develop- nuant in postindustrial society which is characterized by "Iralatively stable birth rates comparable in so-called urban aIICI so—called rural areas, with significant intraregional VEirfiiations due_primarily to ecological specialization within tliea Inetropolitan complex."59 However she fails to develop this idea further. We must move away from the theoretical bias of urban dCHntiriance theory. Freedman himself has suggested that demog— raphers and sociologists alike have shared this bias. further states : He this was the View that urbanization with its accompany- :ing specialization and high rate of mobility inevitably Vvould lead to a growth of secularism and rationality, to 'the declining influence of such traditional forces as :religious faith, to a shattering of traditional family ties and other primary group influences, to a growth of individualism, and to the attachment of the individual to larger, impersonal, and rational organizations. . . . The dominant view among both demographers and sociolo— gists was that as all of the population becomes closely involved in an urban society, family planning would become universal and the size of families planned would continue to decline. . . . A continuing revision of the older View of urban society since the war gives more weight to the persistence of religious and other tradi- tional allegiances. There is growing emphasis on the persistence and even resurgence of the family and other primary groups as the channels through which the larger bureaucratic organizations reach the individual, in 59Janet Abu-Lughod, op. cit., p. 489 (italics mine). 184 larger measure. Urbanization and industrialization are seen as leading to the reorganization of society in new forms rather than to inevitable disorganization and mass anomy. Urban dominance theory suggests the emergence of a mass society in which all traditional differences have disap— pearecL. This is highly unlikely. As Freedman suggests, societqris undergoing a reorganization and new patterns of differrnmdation will emerge. In fact, it is possible that mums former differences will persist if maintained by the differtantiating effects of metropolitan centers on their hinterfiland. It is proposed that the urban-rural fertility differermial is one of these traditional differences that will persist. we must avoid inaccurate interpretations of ecolog— ical5 ... A: we. a“ .3 1r“ av ... 3. .s s c» .a« .~h ~u~ .... u“ we .3 ..M Y‘ e ...u Ci .2 .. .7. .C T. Z. S m. o. .1 it ..u. C .n.. .l r... P.,‘ ‘5 .-. E T. t 3 .n... E 3 t C E L~ v. T . n J O .3. (\ rC t A: e O C T. «L ..I‘ kk has .1 Q» ”H4 «Fu .1 V‘ .‘\ c. L. yr to. at C. ... \u. 1. .J \-5 .'\ 1.! be. 9“ 187 years ago by Firey, Loomis, and Beegle.64 The authors use 'the metropolitan dominance concepts of "field" and "center" to distinguish rural and urban and also speak of the role of highways in bringing rural communities into an interdepen- dent unity, a metropolitan community, in other words. They state: Briefly, highways are binding the field areas into organic, functioning unities and subunities which sur- round and tie in with centers and subcenters. Villages serve as centers for little towns; towns are centers for large fields; and cities function as centers for the largest fields. Each field, with its center, is succes— sively subsumed into the next large one, in hierarchical fashion. Thus there emerges a functional pyramid of field- center "organisms," all bound together by a network of highways. The height of the pyramid and the degree of its functional unity is directly contingent upon the number and layout of its sustaining highways. The authors use a metropolitan dominance framework and describe clearly the structure of a metropolitan community, but unfortunately conclude the convergence of urban and rural areas rather than differentiation. They continue: Such a pyramid implies interaction between rural and urban people, a reduction of their differences, a fusion of their interests. . . . In between these centers and subcenters, as well as out beyond them, in the areas more truly rural, are farm families, whose new proximity 64Walter Firey, Charles P. Loomis, and J. Allan Beegle, "The Fusion of Urban and Rural," in Jean Labatat and Wheaton J. Lane, Highways in Our National Life: A Symposium (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1950), pp. 154-63. Reprinted in P. K. Hatt and A. J. Reiss, Jr., Cities and Society (2nd ed.; Glencoe: The Free Press, 1957), pp. 214-22. 65Ibid., pp. 215—17. # 188 to the city, made possible by the highway, renders them a little less rural and a little more urban than they had been before.66 After noting the possibility of delineating with remarkable precision the gradients which urban cultural patterns take on in the rural areas contiguous to a city, they conclude by saying: Making due allowance for some exceptions and for some degree of variability in the centers, the general prin- ciple still seems to hold that rural areas, in direct proportion to their proximity to urban centers, are becoming culturally urbanized. Since proximity is con- tingent upon time-cost accessibility between country and city, itself a function of highways, the causative agent in this urbanization of rural culture must be evident. It is the highway that has brought city values, ideals, and standards to the country dweller. Notions about life objectives, about loyalties, about modes of living, about consumption tastes, about well-being--all of these are becoming more alike as between country and city. While all this perforce means the loss of quaint, rustic ruralisms, it means, too, the fuller integration of the American people around basic and historic ideals of the nation. More truly than ever before a homogeneous, internally consistent, and universally accepted value system, shared alike by urbanite and ruralite, is coming to characterize American society. The role of the high- way in effecting this cultural rapproachement between country and city has been decisive. It seems that a too hasty conclusion has been posited by these writers: that increased integration of the rural and urban populations necessitates homogeneity. But the notion of the metropolitan community contains the integration of heterogeneous elements into an interdependent whole. Indeed, there are dynamic changes taking place between urban and 6§£E£Q-, p. 217 (italics mine). 67Ibid., p. 222. .1. ‘1 7. Av Tr. ..t. ..t. .. I .aa A: ‘L a: C. i.e.lmi 3 L... r\ it I «C ~Ho .C t i ..f :u T. 189 rural parts of the metropolitan community, but this is not necessarily a move toward the disappearence of urban and rural differences. A reorganization of society by metropol— itanism suggests the emergence or persistence of differences in functional interdependence. Quinn, in his classic text— book on human ecology, points out that homogeneity and func— tional integration are two distinct bases for the classifica- tion of substantive areas. In distinguishing these he says: . . . a homogeneous area is characterized by similaripy of differentiating attributes throughout its extent. For example, a region may be characterized by a hot, dry type of climate, by rugged topography, by a distinctive type of population, or by a characteristic culture. Whatever attributes have been selected for purposes of delimitation, these attributes must show sufficient similarity and importance throughout its entire extent to give character to the area, and at the same time sufficient difference from adjacent territory to mark it off as distinct. In contrast, the integrated area typically includes contrasting_parts organized into a larger areal unit. For example, the diverse sub-areas of a metropolitan region, including the agricultural hinterland with its town, village, and farm communities, and the metropolis with its business center, factory districts, residential areas, and satellite suburbs, together constitute a functioning area unity. The chief attribute of such a metropolitan region is that of inte— gration itself. The contrasting types of sub—areas are welded together in a complex where larger unity itself makes the metropolitan area distinguishable from adja- cent territory. Finally, Bogue seems to suggest that urbanization, characters ized by the emergence of a metropolitan economy, will not have the effect of diminishing geographic differences, but will actually enhance them. He asserts: 68James A. Quinn, Human Ecology_(New York: Prentice- Hall, 1950), p. 39 (italics mine). .» Ce 5 at L” .1 w t A: w». n\~ u. «N. C “V. . v “.V. O nu. L' § ”57' b ..\-~¢ INA-“bus . \’ Uv-l-l‘qr l ‘- 0 5 val-‘6." ‘&\-\$ - a. ‘. ., 1. . “‘Van n» \A\. ‘- \- Q31! ”snce ere: .- ‘ es N . u 190 . . . the notion that progressive urbanization and industrialization will cause these distinctive clusters to disappear cannot be supported either by theory or by observation. In fact, the contrary appears to be true. A market economy seems to cause places to seize upon whatever unique sites, location or physical characteris- tics they have that may provide the basis for profitable specialization. . . . Thus, instead of minimizing geogrophic differences, the modern metropolitan economy may emphasize them. In this process, interregional differences that once were large may disappear, while new differences may appear. Instead of becoming a homogeneous mass, industrialized populations tend to become a patchwork of specialized populations tied together by a geographic as well as intracommunity and intercommunity division of labor.6 In conclusion to our discussion of urban dominance theory, we must propose that urban—rural differences in community social structure will persist. Assuming the eco— logical principle established previously, that fertility is a function of community social structure, we must also insist that urban-rural fertility differences will persist. Urban dominance theory does not lead to this conclusion, since it must posit the eventual blurring of urban—rural differences. We must conclude also that fertility studies which assume an urban dominance theoretical framework do not have a sensitive research design essential to understanding possible differences which may exist in urban—rural fertil- ity behavior. To understand why urban-rural differences will persist, we must move to a consideration of metropoli— tan dominance theory. Though much has already been said 69Donald J. Bogue, "Population Distribution," op, cit., p. 396 (italics mine). 191 concerning metropolitan dominance theory in contrast to urban dominance theory, let us proceed to systematically consider the elements of the former as the preferred theo- retical framework for the analysis of urban—rural fertility differences. Metropolitan Dominance Theory The metropolitan community (or region) is becoming an increasingly important form of organization in modern industrial society. We have established previously the expectation of an orderly spatial distribution of population characteristics within given geographical areas. An essen— tial assumption in metropolitan dominance theory is that the metropolitan center is a primary organizing agent which pro— duces the spatial distribution patterns of community social structure within the metropolitan region or the sphere of influence of the metropolitan center. The economy of the metropolitan community is viewed as "the characteristic and dominant type of modern social and economic organization."70 It is assumed, then, that American society is a "metropoli— tanized" society. Our present day society operates in terms of, and is conditioned by, the metropolis. The metropolitan economy is the modern form of social organization by which man makes effective use of his advanced technology. The 70Donald J. Bogue, The Structure of the Metropolitan CommuniEy, op. cit., p. 8. -.. .... WV- «p t. .3 pl. Er. In 1 ‘ C Li .Ql‘ “1.. «G ...H Mix c AU “U4. 192 pervasive influence of metropolitan centers has spread to such an extent that "the entire area of the United States may be broken down into a series of areas, each of which is dominated by a metropolis."71 If we are to understand how the metropolitan center orders the Spatial distribution of community social struc- tures, we must understand first the nature of the metropol— itan community. The general spatial structure of the metro- politan community was described by R. D. McKenzie some time ago: The metropolitan region thus considered is primarily a functional entity. Geographically it extends as far as the city exerts a dominant influence. It is essen- tially an extended pattern of local communal life based upon motor transportation. Structurally, this new metropolitan regionalism is axiate in form. The basic elements of its patterns are centers, routes and rims. The metropolitan region represents a constellation of centers, the interrelations of which are characterized by dominance and subordination. Every region is orga- nized around a central city or focal point of dominance in which are located the institutions and services that cater to the region as a whole and integrate it with other regions. The business subcenters are rarely com- plete in their institutional or service structure. They depend upon the main center for the more specialized and integrating functions. As McKenzie suggests, the rise of the metropolitan community was made possible by the emergence of rapid trans— portation, especially motor transportation. Prior to the 71Ibid., p. 13. 72R. D. McKenzie, The Metropolitan Community (New York: McGraw—Hill, 1933), p. 70. q. C A .2 l C c.“ C . S O N. G o o . .1 . , r. 0 ML e .s a S r; w. L. 2. 5 ~. 7:. u . 1(a fig Cu 7. « LI r e .3 Qt ... c" :u . O . . ...». o. t E :1 a-.. .2 f .n. J 5 a no 3 C. wt. mt. Min 4w. one. :5. Wu t .1 a a la a . a o‘ H :3 .l c 7 .A ‘Lv 1* ~,Q .1 S in “w 3.. it at «we. .... C MW M» .5 a C u. 0 S F. Au -1 t a c _ .. o. u . cc. 3 .1 . . . .. ,. .... H s c M... m f. 193 development of modern highway systems, in the waterway and railroad eras, the city was in very large degree autonomous of its own rural hinterland. "But the highway has changed all of this. Because of the peculiar superiority of the automobile as a short—distance, small load carrier and as a 'free—agent' whose course and destination need not be confined by water ways or railroad tracks, the advent of highway transportation has meant, for the first time, intimate contact between a city and its hinterland."73 Hence motor transportation has opened up the hinterland in such a way as to increase the interdependence between the central city and surrounding hinterland populations. Inte— gration or interdependence, then, is the essence of the metropolitan community, i.e., the functional interdopendence of metropolitan center and hinterland. As McKenzie states: The super community therefore absorbs varying num- bers of separate local communities into its economic and cultural organization. In this pattern a dominant city--that is, dominant relative to surrounding settle— ment, functions as the integrating unit. . . . In other words, there is developing within the United States . . . a pattern of settlement which may be desig— nated as city regionalism. This new city regionalism differs from the regionalism of former times in that it is a product of contact and division of labor rather than a mere geographic isolation.74 73Walter Firey, Charles P. Loomis, and J. Allan Beegle, op. cit., p. 215. 74R. D. McKenzie, op. cit., p. 313. I . . .. J .... v. c. e C. I 3 ... l. .o . .... e a u S R C ..C “O . .. ...U .. . m“ T. n u 0.. . s l a: . woe ~ 1 C .... «w .r.. 1. .1 F . m 194 But the notion of integration or interdependence of elements with the metropolitan community implies "a division of labor," i.e., a differentiation or specialization of func— tion by place. "The modern metropolitan community, unlike the pre-motor city, obtains its unity through territorial differentiation of specialized functions rather than through mass participation in centrally located institutions."75 Bogue, in describing the function of cities in the metropol— itan community, differentiates between "metropolitan centers" and "hinterland cities." Commenting on the function of the metropolitan center he says: The metropolis is usually the largest and most complex (the farthest removed from the "average" city) of all the cities in the territory. Because it is able to assemble cheaply a varied array of raw materials and products from all parts of the world; because a larger number of specialized components and skills are required in the production of the goods required to sustain human beings at their present level of living; because up to a certain point machine production increases in efficiency with an increased scale of operations; and because cer- tain mutual benefits appear to accrue to business enter— prises from their location in proximity to each other, the large city is able to produce and distribute more varied goods and services than is a smaller city. The more specialized the goods, and the more the goods are amenable to mass production, the greater these industrial and commercial advantages of large cities seem to become. From these facts it has been concluded that the metrop- olis, or modern large and complex city, exercises an organizing and integrating influence on the social and economic life of a broad egpanse of territogy far beyond the civil boundaries, and thereby dominates all other communities within this area.76 75Ibid., p. 71. 76Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., pp. 6-7 (italics mine). ~ 53*- y»--” use“, ”the" r.«*“ id A ... a.“ «L . .mv la . ... “J a. .5 «i ‘iej F‘rke! .. 195 The metropolitan community, then, is really a network of smaller communities, rural and urban, distributed in a definite pattern around a dominant city, and bound together in a territorial division of labor through a dependence upon the activities of the dominant city. It is the metropolitan center, then, which is the organizing agent of inter—commu— nity differentiation. Communities lying in this region about the metropolitan city, drawn into a division of labor with this center, exchange for specialized goods and ser- vices of the metropolis such other products as can most effectively be produced from the resources in their immedi- ate locality. All subordinate communities become dependent upon metropolitan markets, including farm operators who regulate their activities to produce those products which will yield them the greatest return in the metropolitan market. But the metropolitan center is not just an economic center; nor does it influence only the economic activities of its hinterland communities. With the exchange of mate- rial goods there is also an exchange of ideas and human values. "The metropolis appears to have become the focal point not only of our material activities, but of much of our moral and intellectual life as well."77 Bogue, in his attempt to demonstrate the pervading dominance of the 77Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., p. 6. metropolis, activities , :raée, serr hwe'xcer, fr | I “ "LQYV‘ - ’- VaLV-VAA... Anl» less clear] L, ‘3 tL Ffi~l ~ .JAblaer ‘1‘: 5“ N 511’s Ha \. 5‘ ‘K WY q‘uifi: t':+ .. ‘ Ik‘ h I .mEr 1P 1 A f‘ 0.1“- "is l‘r-y‘ O‘jn CFC: ¢.\‘ :flr‘; nu“... .dl Stru 1‘32} «lLan er, \. 196 metropolis, concentrated on what he termed "human sustenance activities," viz., the functions of retail trade, wholesale trade, services, and manufacturing. Bogue does not deny, however, that dominance of an equally intense or identical pattern might operate in other human activities which are less clearly related to human sustenance. In fact he defi~ nitely feels that ”many other conditions of life undoubtedly are subject to control or modification by the central city. The complete structure of the metropolitan community may include the functions of finance, government, education, religion, and innumerable other aspects of the institutional composition of the individual hinterland community."78 Though the notion of metropolitan dominance in its original conception contains many economic overtones, it is clear that the theoretical framework can and must be employed to consider the organizing effect the metropolitan center has on all activities of hinterland communities. The all-inclu— sive nature of metropolitan dominance permits the assumption that almost any community activity is influenced by the metropolis. These comments suggest the need to consider the manner in which fertility behavior is influenced indirectly through the organizing effect the central city has on the social structure of communities which lie within the metro— politan region itself. 781bid., p. 61. _ l"+.h!.v~ ' ‘n “11...“. C.. . ~ a; C 0. s45 51. , .rzctlons . “'0 197 But metropolitan dominance cannot be understood only in terms of the function of the metropolitan center. The interdependence of central city and hinterland must also be recognized. The high density of population in the central city precludes the possibility that food stuffs for the population or raw materials for industry can be provided within the central city. It is impossible for the city to be self-sufficient, hence, the need to consider the function of the hinterland. Hawley assumes this distinction when he describes the community as "comprised of two generalized unit parts, the center and the adjoining outlying area. In the one are performed the processing and service functions, and in the other are carried on the raw-material producing functions. The two develop together, each presupposing the other."79 Bogue in his investigation of the metropolitan community also emphasized the interdependent relationship of the central city and its hinterland: The one situational factor which Gras80 holds to be absolutely essential for the development of a city aspirant to metropolitan status is the possession of a hinterland, "a tributary adjacent territory, rich in natural resources accompanied by a productive population and accessible by means of transportation." We are warned by Gras not to overemphasize either the metrop- olis or the hinterland in considering the metropolitan organization. It is true that in studying this organization we are inclined to emphasize the great metropolitan center, but 79Amos Hawley, op. cit., p. 245. 80N. S. B. Gras, An Introduction to Economic History (New York: Harper, 1922), quotations from pp. 185—87. t. .3 v. n J 72.5; ’ , J5 ‘0 Ac 5 a ‘3 LL 3. xfiu . -;N II. at Q. d a: Win ... c v‘ o: it A.» «\~ .2 «C 3 .1 c by; .l . . C ... S\ O .5 (... C. 3. 2.. .VA to A: 198 to forget the large dependent district would be fatal to a correct understanding of the subject. Perhaps, indeed, it is somewhat incorrect to speak of the area as depen- dent upon the center, for though that is true, the center is also dependent upon the outlying area with its towns, villages, and scattered homesteads. Interdependence of parts is really the key to the whole thing.81 Though this caveat was voiced rather strongly by Gras and Bogue, there seems to be some evidence that it has not been adhered to rigorously by others. Grigg claims: The proponents of this position (the interdependency of central city and hinterland) emphasized one aspect of this principle of dominance—~the function of the center-— and have ignored the second--the hinterland. They have taken Gras's statement of the relationship of the two and have failed to consider the broader implications of his writings. Gras points out the necesSity of a hinter— land for the existence of a metropolitan center, but at the same time he insists that you cannot reify one at the expense of the other. Indeed, implied in the writing is the injunction that extent and degree of functional inte— gration imposed on the hinterland by the metropolitan center is an empirical question wanting to be demon— strated rather than an ad hoc assumption to be treated as a reality. Thus, the ecologist finds himself in the position of stating dominance exists because metropol— itan centers exist ipso facto; and the concept of the hinterland is dragged along behind, not because they (pig) exist, but because it is obvious Ehat each metro— politan center must have a hinterland.8 Grigg calls for more intensive consideration of and possible refinement of the concept of hinterland in metropolitan dominance theory. It is essential that the hinterland be given due consideration not only because of its interdepen- dence with a metropolitan center, but also because the 81Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., pp. 7—8. 82Charles M. Grigg, "A Proposed Model for Measuring the Ecological Process of Dominance," Social Forces, XXXVI, No. 1 (December, 1957), 628. Fm "ance “var-o. :zanizati have some » ' ‘ +1fl!‘ 1 - fi ~‘V00 -4; L.. I“ " 1 n" " .V‘n “AaH JCUR‘ . Q 7 n 2.1‘Vnnfi s».:-: d—e . . “‘u‘ ‘ - ..- er ‘v-p‘ Ct. -‘ ‘.U (1.) (...) 199 dominance of a metropolitan center is reflected in the organization of the hinterland and the hinterland itself may have some bearing on its own internal pattern of organization. We shall consider this point later. At this juncture we may assert that the theory of metropolitan dominance states that the metropolitan center more and more controls the conditions of life of the popula- tion in the areas surrounding the central city. The hinter- land populations, as a result, are spatially organized with reference to the metropolitan center. We should next con— sider the concept of dominance, the means by which the hinterland is controlled. Bogue considered the concept of dominance to a great extent and suggested that "dominance, in its ecological meaning, is a special kind of control over a community of interfunctioning units."83 Simply put, the metropolitan center establishes and controls the conditions of life which set limits to the activities of the other communities in its sphere of influence. The net effect is a multiple— community complex, a constellation of communities, which may be termed the metropolitan community in deference to its dominant central city. The social structure of each of these communities will be an adaptation to the conditions estab— lished by the metropolitan center. 83Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., p. 10. 9 a nu» Arab A—uqnc“ VI «~‘\A¢O C . - ~ A C a a“ ”(do 1" h. ~ :~ 0 K I s I ‘4 ‘3 Wu 3.. .1 +5 3 ...H h... I Cy v. \Q I .ma rm... . ‘ r s: 7V Y n E C : 200 This is the nature of dominance, but how does one operationalize it? Bogue suggests that if a definite non- random distribution of attributes can be demonstrated, pat— terned with respect to the metropolis, it can be inferred that the distribution of these attributes is "controlled" to some extent by factors associated with the metropolis.84 But dominance is not to be considered a fixed attribute, but a variable. The amount of control exercised over the communities of the metropolitan region will vary with the size of the dominating center and the accessibilioy_(dis- tance) of the hinterland community to the dominating center. Accessibility is assumed to be a variable which covaries with dominance. The task of delimiting areas of like degree of dominance is a problem of delimiting areas of like degree of accessibility. The metropolis is a metropolis because of its superior ability to serve and be served by the hinterland. In terms of time, cost, and expenditure of energy the entire area can enter more easily into a division of labor with a city located at a highly accessible point. Exchange and interaction with a city located at the most inaccessible point could be achieved only at a maximum expenditure of time, cost, and energy. Since time, cost, and energy are all elements of life which must be conserved in order to ensure most economical survival, it can be reasoned that, since these elements vary with accessibility, the following assumption can be made: varying dogrees of accessibilipy must represent varying degrees of interaction with the metropolitan center.85 84Ibid., pp. 14—15. 85Ibid., p. 21. L L Y:‘“r\ Q F‘s-l an USO to '1 V \ iIC) . C H 1:” duo.“ pant A-Ulob L L . 337.13 .1 .a C A‘bv. 3" ‘5..( Q... “I. .r-‘w‘Q" D 00 o ‘ fin u.. 0 tut h at Zatio 1' § larger 201 Because of the importance of motor vehicle transportation in the development and establishment of dominant metropolitan centers, distance to be traveled may be expected to covary with accessibility. The distance to be traveled limits the opportunity to transport goods, services, and persons from hinterland communities to the metropolitan center. "One permanent requirement for changing the location of any object is the necessity of overcoming distance."86 Hence, it is understood that varying distance of a hinterland com— munity from a metropolitan center reflects varying degrees of dominance. Size, as an attribute of the dominating center, is also an indicator of dominance. It is expected that the larger the metropolitan center, the greater will be its organizing influence on the hinterland, the closer the integration of the central city and its hinterland, and the larger will be the hinterland area which can be effectively influenced by the metropolitan center. Increases in the size of a population are related to the degree of special— ization attainable by that population. Hawley points out that "population size imposes limits on both the extent of specialization and the number of different activities that may be carried on simultaneously. . . . In a small popula- tion the degree of specialization of activity is necessarily 86Ibid. slight. On- th creases the ex 11:35 this at I n ~ . ”171“.” an” ‘ V‘ us‘..;,u div 1‘. .4 AA u n N! - . 5 e a up ‘1 ‘3? Ira oesn‘h‘,“u..u. 202 slight. On the other hand, every increment in size in— creases the extent to which specialization may be devel— oped."87 Bogue, in describing the metropolitan center, the largest city in the metropolitan region, emphasizes its greater capacity for specialization of activities. He then links this attribute of the metropolitan center to the orga— nizing and integrative influence it exercises over the hinterland.88 Hence the larger the metropolitan center, the greater its specialization powers, and the greater its integrative effect on the hinterland. Therefore in opera- tionalizing the concept of metropolitan dominance both dis- tance from the metropolitan center and size of the metropol— itan center should be taken into consideration. Now at this point we may briefly summarize by saying that the metropolitan center and its hinterland are func- tionally interdependent. But the metropolitan community is a network of communities, including both urban and rural populations, which are territorially differentiated by the dominant influence of the metropolitan center. The degree of dominance of the metropolitan center over its hinterland communities is a function of size and distance. We have also established the fact that the metropolitan center has a controlling influence, not only on the sustenance 87Amos Hawley, op. cit., p. 122. 88Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., pp. 5—6. activities of social struct: or: the whole ; reconsider ths Warlae ' Aauv ‘,u. P I OI COIITCJIHU’ V A "V‘u 30». (.e 85:011.: .5 y - .63.: ‘ {wry-n _ ahu L U‘ a \ 203 activities of hinterland communities, but on the entire social structure of such communities, and perhaps indirectly on the whole gamut of community activities. We must now reconsider the effect of the metropolitan center on its hinterland. What patterns of territorial differentiation of community social structural variables might we expect to accrue among hinterland communities? The most common type of analysis of the influence of metropolitan centers on hinterland communities has been in terms of gradients (concentric zones) which extend out from the metropolitan center. In such studies it is usually hypothesized that the hinterland will be spatially organized with reference to the metropolis and that this organization will manifest itself in a series of gradients in the charac- teristics of the population along the dimension, distance from the metropolis. The fact that such gradients exist has been documented by numerous studies emphasizing a wide vari- ety of indices of population characteristics.89 Unfortunately 89A selected list of such studies might include the following: Theodore R. Anderson and Jane Collier, "Metropol— itan Dominance and the Rural Hinterland," Rural Sociology, XXI (June, 1956), 152-57; Edmund deS. Brunner and J. H. Kolb, Rural Social Trends (New YOrk: McGraw-Hill, 1933), Ch. V; Otis D. Duncan and Albert J. Reiss, Jr., Social Characteris- tics of Urban and Rural Communities, 1950 (New YOrk: John Wiley, 1956), Ch. XIII; O. D. Duncan, "Gradients of Urban Influence on the Rural Population," The Midwest Sociologist, XVIII, No. 1 (Winter, 1956), 27-30; 0. D. Duncan, "Note on Farm Tenancy and Urbanization," Journal of Farm Economics, ZXXXVIII, No. 4 (November, 1956), 1043-47; John Stoeckel and J. Allan Beegle, "The Relationship between the Rural-Farm Age Structure and Distance from a Metropolitan Area," Rural I‘- l ltc . I033 O 1.: u‘v " "I. A. 0m 1 .0 o 2.— .75 I l V ‘ OI COLE] m p o d ices n q 813 ray-‘0. 5“ \— *Ce 83' 5h .. 3. nul OI DO :4“ ch 12:”: 311Gb S. 204 the test of the gradient pattern in the hinterland of a metropolitan center is a test of only p§£E_of the metropol- itan dominance theory. In fact, the gradient test is a test for both metropolitan dominance and urban dominance theory, and does not differentiate between the two. Gradient studies usually conclude that the hinterland population manifests a pattern of decreasing (or increasing) incidence of population characteristics (depending upon which vari— ables are employed), as one moves away from the central city. Empirical findings of gradient studies have been used to determine, for example, the territorial extent of the influ- ence exerted by a central city, or the average of a number of central cities; the difference between rural populations located adjacent to cities and those removed from cities, with the amount of difference indicating how much the strength of urban influence is conditioned by distance; how the gradient of one particular characteristic may be differ- ent from that of another, with such differences suggesting the spheres where urban influence is most pronounced; or how much size conditions the amount of urban influence exerted Sociology, XXXI, No. 3 (September, 1966), 346-54; Harold F. (Goldsmith and James H. Copp, "Metropolitan Dominance and (Agriculture," Rural Sociology, XXIX, No. 4 (December, 1964), 385-95; E. T. Hiller, "Extension of Urban Characteristics into Rural Areas," Rural Sociology, VI (September, 1941), 242-57; and Warren S. Thompson and Nelle E. Jackson, "Fer- tility in Rural Areas in Relation to Their Distance from Cities, 1930," Rural Sociology, V (June, 1940), 143-62. surrou: 01‘. ath I etrop: sin .1. o. a h .nu .M +. .. at an at flu a u .-. .2 oL . n ‘ - r5 5 a- s C I. .- ‘t- .\r V: d .0 \ my ad w“ n1. A: . . .5 AL . ...ifi Z; a» A—v . odd C 15 Co 5/ I Q» «luv . in) -~« 6 a: 7 in; 205 on surrounding rural territory when gradients are examined in relation to the size of cities. These studies tell as much of the gradient_principle of metropolitan dominance theory (and urban dominance theory as well) but little in terms of the principle of differentia- utign, which is also an essential part of metropolitan domi- nance theory (but not of urban dominance theory). An excel— 90 draws especial attention to this lent article by Martin deficiency in metropolitan dominance research. This arti- cle is not an empirical study but an attempt to summarize and synthesize what research has been done dealing with ecological changes taking place in the rural sectors of satellite areas (hence, he does not consider the entire range of hinterland components of a metropolitan community). Martin uses the two broad principles of gradient and differ- entiation as "organizing devices" for ordering the results of recent studies. With respect to the gradient principle, "the extent of urban influenced changes in rural areas varies inversely with distance to the nearest city and 91 directly with the size of that city," he finds a wealth 90Walter T. Martin, "Ecological Change in Sattelite Rural Areas," American Sociological Review, XXII (April, 1957), 173—83. Also reprinted in George A. Theodorson, Studies in Human Ecology (Evanston: Row, Peterson, 1961), pp. 607-16. 91Ibid., p. 610. \ AC, (1.;5 p. v! V‘ s n .1 ‘ V‘, to 2‘58.‘ ‘1»; .. c0 accivi‘ i 0 .cc . ‘ de‘ . . QQ. ‘\ 5'0va fi“ {no ’10 of extirl 5.5% “y r. ,‘ r. nu \Q ..u 5m ...u. 1 CU. MG e S .0. r it T. +.t 3 0. 9...!“ . 3‘ 2w «.ma ... LL no. C Q» nu MYCI .|« No &L in ...i .... ...... m a e e e .1 i e c r. .... I ~ .s . 3N: l 2 s .. . i at .l .. e enure‘il‘a .1 .. YA pan .9» a» 206 of empirical studies which document gradient patterns for the deconcentration of industry, population, and business activities, occupational composition, rural land values, nature of the farming enterprise, income, age and sex com- position, fertility, educational achievement, and partici- pation in urban activities. The second principle, differ- entiation, is to be considered complementary, rather than contradictory, of the gradient principle, although "the two are partially independent in the sense that demonstrated tenability of the gradient principle provides no basis for evaluating the differentiation principle; on the other hand, acceptance of the second indicates that the first holds true. . . ."92 What Martin says of the principle of differ- entiation is crucial to this thesis: The second principle (differentiation) . . . holds that these influences are extended selectively rather than diffusing uniformily, and that the over all effect is to transform the homogeneity of the rural territory into an urban-like heterogeneity with specialization of labor, differentiation of subareas, and functional inter- dependency of parts. In spite of the almost complete lack of research concerned with this principle, it would seem to have as much or greater implication for changes occurring in rural areas than does the gradient prin— ciple, which has been dealt with so frequently. The differentiation principle concerns the dynamics of the relationship between the rural and urban sectors of the economy, and the increasing integration of rural areas into the great regional urban complexes. While this idea has been stressed by McKenzie and others, there is a surprising lack of empirical research. ..J r\ 1. 4| .-. v. ¢\ .\ .L .. a. 7.. x: .l r LL .1 at 3; AV .c ... .3 nu C» «a O .hd vi +» a» O L . ow .W O nu C. C n . an at a at r C L t h... .C D. A: n .nu .1 My n, ..n L» u“ 04]“ \C ~ u r 3» .1s Zn .» an .. . g i. . 1| 4 w o F a: .. LI. . A: m c A: r; .3 . t a - a1. CL LL ...y .1.“ . W“ 1an T ML. «r- .... .nd V- O at «C .t h» “A an n ‘L No F. L t :4 hi. .3 O b b e no . t T“ .1¢ A.» .hd .l -l «\U C 1‘ Ad s i 0 IBM T. y k ‘1. l!“- :50 liCor i 207 The point Martin makes, then, is that an important element of metropolitan dominance, i.e., the differentiating effect the metropolitan center exerts on the hinterland communities, even within the same distance zone from the central city, for both urban and rural communities, is in need of empirical testing. The crucial issue to consider at this stage of metropolitan dominance research, then, is not that metropol— itan centers exert a controlling influence over hinterland communities or that its influence wanes as distance increases, but that the metropolitan center exerts a differentiating influence, transforming both urban and rural communities into a functional interdependency of specialized parts. Studies using the gradient principle tend more toward a comparative study of the metropolitan center and its hinter- land communities. The differentiation principle, on the other hand, requires a different dimension of comparison. If metropolitan centers do exert a differentiating influence on hinterland communities, then an important comparison to be made is between different classes of hinterland commu— nities. Martin indicates that he is aware of only one study dealing with this problem. This study, by Kish, classified incorporated places by distance zones from the central city and demonstrated conclusively that for a variety of varie ables the cities of the distant zones made up a relatively homogeneous universe while those in the inner zones were «.3 n3 ct ck C‘Yfi“ ystvv 03“ us .nyy. u: ‘Hba‘by m 1‘1‘AFR sO‘Y' more c h C Co. F. ll \q wlt . hr- # LC “ 3 1e g, 208 highly differentiated on the same counts.94 But Kish's study dealt only with incorporated places and excluded rural communities. Furthermore the incorporated places were those found only within the immediate metropolitan ring to the exclusion of those lying in the more outlying areas. In concluding his article Martin states that: . . . it seems highly probable that the rural sectors of the satellite areas, like the urban sectors, more and more consist of well differentiated subareas as the in- fluence of the central city is extended increasingly throughout the larger metropolitan area. The changing patterns in population density, age and sex composition, occupational composition, and land values, to name a few characteristics, are societal adjustments in the satel- lite areas to the evolving spatial organization of the metropolitan community. Martin's comment clearly suggests that further com— parisons of the differentiating effects of metropolitan centers must concentrate on the differences that accrue between urban and rural hinterland communities. Hence we should expect that metropolitan centers exert a different impact on urban hinterland communities than on rural hinter— land communities. On the basis of these comments we should be able to formulate some hypotheses concerning the differen- tiating influence which metropolitan centers have on their respective hinterlands. Recall that earlier in this chapter 94Leslie Kish, "Differentiation in Metropolitan .Areas," American Sociolggical Review, XIX (August, 1954), 388-98. ' 95Walter T. Martin, op. cit., pp. 615-16. «G A: C A“ I U..b.'. 3» ..l T. ‘V- 9 PA- A UVVA. ual-T. ...Sr b - .l .c L . «G h.§_" ‘~“\.i ~ “9" c.“ a 209 we accepted a major assumption of ecological analysis, that community social structure indicators will manifest a defi- nite nonrandom distribution pattern in social space and that fertility behavior, operationalized on a residential area level, will be a function of community social structure in both urban and rural populations. With the introduction of metropolitan dominance theory, we now assume that this non— random distribution of community social structure indicators is due to the pervading influence of metropolitan centers in their respective hinterlands. Metropolitan centers, then, are the determining agents of the social and economic orga— nizational makeup of both urban and rural hinterland commu- nities. It is assumed that, given the differentiating effect of metropolitan centers, community social structure in the urban hinterland will manifest different patterns of specializing than the rural hinterland. Accepting distance and size as measures of the dominance of metropolitan cen- ters, and the differentiating effect of metropolitan centers on their hinterlands, it is hypothesized that: 1. Community social structure is a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. a. Distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will manifest a different impact on com- munity social structures in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. 2. Fertility behavior is a function of community social structure and distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. a. Community social structure and distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will mani- fest a different impact on fertility behavior in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. ‘. n“ .329 metrosoxl 6 pl- .4.-C* . n: rura .ys.‘.|.L. envy“. w q 9 H . ~~.‘Ar >1. :. Wu C» v. U 1' to L‘. Ml CO”' uterla: QM yg ' Vs .Lb ‘ [1' Oo§y A '5‘ *U\. i h N “VJ. (A . . "vn. O 210 To this point we have discussed various aspects of metropolitan dominance theory. Our hypotheses emphasize the differentiating effect of metropolitan dominance on urban and rural hinterlands. If our discussion of this theory is terminated at this point, we shall be in danger of violating the caveat expressed earlier, that of overemphasizing the role of the metropolitan center and overlooking the impor— tance of the hinterland. Let us reconsider the place of the hinterland in metropolitan dominance theory. If we return to Bogue's study of the structure of the metropolitan community, we will capture an important point often overlooked by other studies of metropolitan dom- inance. Many such studies grant the attribute of dominance only to the metropolitan center. Bogue, emphasizing the point that the metropolitan community is a "community of local communities," constituting a central city and several hinterland communities, recognized that "all local communi— ties in the metropolitan community are considered to possess some degree of dominance over some portion of the hinter- land."96 For this reason he found it necessary to adopt as his unit of analysis the individual local community, since each community exercises some influence within the hinter- land. In this connection he stated: The hinterland contains a great variety of communi- ties, ranging from cities of more than 100,000 inhab- itants to small villages and local farming communities. 96Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., p. 30. .1 fly «.aa Pu «a Po 1_ . A: .3 Y. Q» _ u T. 3. .l o. ~U «v ad a: C . a .. v . .l . t . i. E :u a. . . . .D I Y. Y. raca J» E C ‘“348 9' ‘W h ‘5‘.- i,P\.-y. 211 For this reason it cannot easily be assumed that the conditions set by the metropolis force one pattern of adjustment in all areas about the metropolis. Nor can it be assumed that all hinterland communities are oriented solely toward the metropolis. . . . This general observation makes it evident that some system of classifying the hinterland communities must be adopted, and that this classification must be in terms of amount of influence exercised by the principal hinter— land communities.9/ From this Bogue proceeded to propose a fourfold classifica- tion of hinterland communities corresponding to different steps in the dominance continuum: Metropolitan centers . . . . . . Dominants Hinterland cities (urban) . . . Subdominants Rural—nonfarm populations (rural-nonfarm). . . . . . . . Influents Rural-farm populations (rural-farm) . . . . . . . . . Subinfluents It is understood that "decreasing values along this scale refer to two types of change in dominance: (l) decreasing range or area of dominance, and (2) decreasing number of functions over which dominance is exercised."98 Although Bogue considered in his analysis only the first two levels of dominance to the neglect of the rural-nonfarm and rural- farm populations, it is essential for a comprehensive View of metropolitan dominance to take into consideration the potential influence of the metropolitan center on all three hinterland areas: urban, rural-nonfarm and rural—farm 97Ibid., p. 18. 98Ibid. hinterla: C) . tie metro; ‘HCYQ he ““h" Cu QC J- vlslalizes poiltan CC :ug " u C i 3 x, ‘ioglcal Pr Dir, 1957) tnree‘folr‘i 212 hinterland communities.99 The present study is considering all three types of hinterlands as well as the local commu— nity as its unit of analysis.100 Getting back to our problem, what are the implica- tions of the observation that all local communities in the metropolitan community exert some degree, great or small, of dominance? If the metropolis cannot be expected to set the conditions for adjustment in all areas of the hinterland and if some hinterland communities are not solely oriented to the metropolitan center, what other source of influence is there operating in the hinterland to account for the non— random distribution of structural attributes in space? Furthermore, if the power of the metropolitan center to control the conditions of life, to which hinterland commu- nities adjust, wanes with increasing distance, what other 99Bogue's is the only study that I am aware of that visualizes the metropolitan community in four parts: metro- politan center, urban hinterland, rural—nonfarm hinterland, and rural-farm hinterland. Other metropolitan dominance studies employ a three-fold classification: metropolitan center, urban hinterland, and rural hinterland. See, for example, Lewis Jones, "The Hinterland Reconsidered," Amer- igan Sociological Review, XX (February, 1955), 40-44; and Charles M. Grigg, "A Proposed Model for Measuring the Eco- logical Process of Dominance," Social Forces, XXXVI (Decem— ber, 1957), 128-31. Some urban dominance studies use a three—fold classification also, but slightly different to fit the theory: urban centers (by metropolitan and non- metropolitan status), rural—nonfarm and rural-farm. See, for example, 0. D. Duncan, "Gradients for Urban Influence on the Rural Population," The Midwest Sociologist, XVIII (Winter, 1956) , 27—30. 100See Chapter I, p. 62, for the specific definitions Of urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm communities. Census definitions are employed on a county basis. source of land area: he answers tfl A" \J C ' ‘1 CON 213 source of influence might there be in the outlying hinter- land areas of the metropolitan region? These questions must be answered in order to maintain the basic assumption in ecological analysis, that there exists a non-random distri- bution of structural attributes in space. It is suggested that though metropolitan dominance is an important determi- nant of this non-random distribution of structural attri- butes, it is not capable of accounting for all the variation of structural attributes in hinterland communities. Grigg has written two articles which have something to say concerning the problem under consideration.101 In the later article Grigg and Vance attempt a synthesis of ecological (actually metropolitan dominance) studies and regional studies. Both approaches can be examined from the point of view of structure, process and content. The authors conclude, however, that structure is the only basis for synthesis. This leaves structure--the basic element in area study and the forte of both regionalist and ecologist-— as a basis for synthesis. Somewhere in between intra— metropolitan ecology devoted to its mosaic of natural areas and the homogeneous region is found the analysis 101Charles M. Grigg, "A Proposed Model for Measuring the Ecological Process of Dominance," Social Forces, XXXVI (December, 1957), 128-31; Charles M. Grigg and Rupert Vance, "Regionalism and Ecology: A Synthesis?" Florida State University Research Reports in Social Science, III, No. 2 (August, 1960), l—ll. 214 of inter-community ecology. The regionalist can partic- ipate in this because he sees the region developing as a constellation of communities. The ecologist sees this as the study of inter-metropolitan dominance and integra— tion-—what R. D. McKenzie called the "new city regional— ism."102 This "analysis of inter-community ecology" requires a con— sideration of the structure of the homogeneous and metropol- itan region as a "constellation of communities," each with its own orbit of influence. After applying two models, one of homogeneous subregions and the other of metropolitan dom— inance, to rates of population change in the South, the authors conclude that . . . in an agricultural society the homogeneous sub— region is the most appropriate spatial model to use. However, (with) the development of cities, the spatial model has to be modified to allow for the effect of large metropolitan centers on the region. The most appropriate model then is one which attempts to express the relationship between the center and its hinterland. This relationship can best be expressed in some measure of distance. This conclusion suggests that there is a dynamic change tak- ing place in hinterland regions. Metropolitan centers are becoming more and more influential in ordering their hinter- land in some consistent pattern along a continuum of dis— tance. This conclusion also suggests, however, that in out- lying hinterland areas where metropolitan dominance is not as influential, i.e., in the more rural areas of the hinter— land, regional environmental factors may be operative in effecting inter—community ecological patterns. 102Ibid., p. 4. 103Ibid., p. 10. 215 The purpose of Grigg's earlier paper, in connection with the above comments, was to question the pervasiveness of metropolitan dominance in the United States.104 Grigg raises the question as to whether it can be shown that other environmental factors rather than dominance can explain the nonrandom distribution of attributes in space. Grigg con- structs a research design which attempts to answer this question. As any test of the hypotheses of metropolitan dom- inance would have to postulate other sources of non- random distribution, we will establish two additional sources other than the influence of the metropolitan center. These will be called rural patterns and urban patterns. Just as metropolitan dominance results in metropolitan structure, the rural and urban result in typical structures on non-random distributions.105 What Girgg's model assumes, then, is that all three elements of the metropolitan community (the metropolitan center, urban hinterland, and rural hinterland) may influence the nonrandom distribution of attributes in space. His finding that urban centers are chiefly responsible for nonrandom patterns of population change in the South suggests a type of dynamic model of urbanization. Remote agricultural areas may first be influenced by their natural environment. As urbanization continues, these areas come under the influence of urban centers, but as urbanization takes on the form of metropolitanism, metropolitan centers become the organizing 104Charles M. Grigg, op. cit., p. 128. 105Ibid., p. 129. It..‘.l\“k t‘ 216 agents of the hinterland. The point to be made, however, is that hinterland communities themselves may have natural environmental conditions which on a broad scale determine the nonrandom distribution of structural attributes in out- lying areas. The more distant the community from a metro— politan center and the less influence exerted on the hinter- land community, the greater the possibility that environmen— tal factors determine the nonrandom distribution of commu— nity structural characteristics. It is assumed that, given the tendency for urban populations to concentrate in close proximity to metropolitan centers and the tendency for the rural-farm population to be dispersed in the outlying areas,106 rural hinterland communities will show the greater tendency to be influenced by local environmental factors than urban hinterland communities. These ideas are not new with Grigg, however, Anderson and Collier, in an article published earlier than Grigg's, employed a research design to test both metropolitan dominance and urban dominance theory. They concluded that: These findings tend to cast doubt on the hypothesis of metropolitan (as opposed to urban) dominance, and even cast some doubt on the notion of urban dominance over the rural hinterland. That is, when variations in the gradients were found (in connection with size of farm), the statistically explanatory factor which ex- plained the variation proved to be a characteristic of the rural areas (type of farming) rather than a charac- teristic of urban areas. This finding seems to indicate that the gradients result from a variety of forces, only 106Donald J. Bogue, op. cit., p. 35. 217 some of which can be said to be concentrated in the metrgpolis and hence contribute to the concept of met- rgpolitan dominanceIlU/ Hence it is possible that internal characteristics of the rural areas themselves may be an important factor in account— ing for inter-community variation. Bogue said somewhat the same thing at even a much earlier time: Within this multiple-community complex, which may be called the metropolitan community in deference to its dominant species, the individual local community must occupy a subordinate position. The activities of the local community are a function not only of its immediate localityy but also of the relative ecological position with respect to the dominant metrgpolis.IU87 Thus Bogue recognized that the nonrandom distribution of community structural attributes is a function of BEER metropolitan dominance and conditions of the local community. This implies, then, that if the influence of the metropoli- tan center, in other words, if distance and size of the met- ropolitan center could be controlled, we should be able to measure the relative influence of the local hinterland com— munity, urban or rural, in determining its own activity and structural patterns. Now recalling our earlier hypothesis that community social structure is a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center and that fertility behavior 107Theodore R. Anderson and Jane Collier, "Metropol- itan Dominance and the Rural Hinterland," Rural Sociology, XXI (June, 1956), 157. 108Ibid., p. 13. 218 is a function of both of these, it stands to reason that, if the influence of a dominating metropolitan center(ixa, its size and distance) can be controlled or held constant, then we should be able to measure the influence of local community conditions alone on fertility behavior. On the basis of this reasoning we may propose a third hypothesis: 3. Community fertility behavior in both urban and rural hinterlands is not only a function of the size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center, but also a function of conditions of its own immediate locality, since all local communities in the metro- politan region possess some degree of dominance over some portion of the hinterland. Since urban hinterland communities tend to concentrate in closer proximity to metropolitan centers than rural hinter- land communities, we should expect metropolitan centers to have a greater influence in ordering community social struc- tural patterns in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. A fourth hypothesis may be stated: 4. Community fertility behavior is more a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan cen- ter in the urban hinterland, but more a function of local community social structure in the rural hinter- land, when distance and size of the dominating metro- politan center are controlled. There is one final aspect to consider with respect to the dominance of metropolitan centers on their urban and rural hinterlands. We have established the fact that metro- politan centers vary with respect to the amount of dominance and extent of the area of dominance. It is also a fact that a considerable amount of difference exists among various geographic divisions of the nation with respect to the level <1 219 of development of the metropolitanization process. Although there are several ways by which one could demonstrate the intensity of metropolitanization within the geographic divi- sions, considering the distribution of population by metro— politan status does allow us an approximate measure of these differences. This information is provided in Table 16. Although the nation as a whole reflects almost two-thirds of its population residing in standard metropolitan statistical areas, the geographic divisions manifest a range from a high of 82 percent for the Middle Atlantic to a low of 36 percent for the East South Central. The geographic divisions of New England, Middle Atlantic, Pacific, and East North Cen- tral indicate metropolitanization levels greater than the nation; West North Central, Mountain, and all three Southern divisions lower than the nation. The question now arises, how can metropolitan dom- inance theory cope with interdivisional variation with respect to the metropolitanization process? Several comments in the previous discussion of metropolitan dominance theory have described metropolitan dominance as an emerging pattern of organization for communities in the nation. The data of Table 16 merely indicate the possibility that in some geo- graphic divisions compared with others metropolitan centers are perhaps more influential "organizing agents" of their hinterlands. If this is true, we would expect to find that the influence of metropolitan centers, measured in terms of . CC: .1): ianau 1: q 220 .ma magma .Aaoma .moflmmo mcfluzflum ucmfich>ow ".U.Q .aovmcflnmmzv ealflavom uuommm Hmcflm .mumEESm mmumum woufisb .musmuanmch mo Hwnfisz .omma "cowumasmmm mo mamcmo .m .D .mSmcmo may mo samusm .m.D "mousom m m.om mae.v m.me mmn.oa mmH.Hm unmaumm a «.am hom.m m.me mem.m mmm.o :Hmucsoz m m.o¢ mmm.n m.mm moo.m Hmm.oa Hmuucmo nusom ummz m o.¢o oom.n 0.0m «em.¢ omo.ma Hmnpcmo nusom ummm o m.me Hmm.ma N.om Heo.ma mem.mm oflucmana nusom m n.9m mme.m m.m¢ oom.o emm.ma Hmuusmo npuoz ummz a m.mm Hmm.HH H.ne emm.¢m mmm.mm Hmuucmo ruuoz pmmm H m.mH mam.o m.am amm.nm moa.¢m onucmaua mavens m e.mm oHH.m m.on mom.a mom.oa ecmamam zmz . o.em mm¢.oo o.mo mmm.mHH mmm.mha mmumpm wanna: QOHDMNHQmu ucmoumm Hmnfidz unmoumm Hmnfisz coauwasmom aOHmH>HQ naaomoupmz Hmuoa wan mmumum emuaco an xcmm m.¢m2m mwnmuso m.¢m2m meHmcH Am.ooo CH aw>flm mumnfiscv coma "msumum Gmuwaom IouuoE >9 .mconH>Ho tam mmumum ompwcb may Ga coaumasmom mo coflusnwuumfln .ma mamas 221 distance and size of the dominating metropolitan center, is more important in accounting for the spatial distribu- tion of community social structural attributes, and as a result community fertility behavior, in both urban and rural hinterlands, in the more metropolitan geographic divisions compared with the less metropolitan divisions. On this basis we may formulate a fifth hypothesis: 5. In the more metropolitan geographic divisions com— pared with the less metropolitan geographic divi- sions, size and distance of a dominating metropol— itan center are more important in accounting for variation in community social structure and fertil— ity behavior in both urban and rural hinterland communities. But there remains more to be said concerning the effects of emerging metropolitanization as the new mode of organization for hinterland communities. On the basis of a dynamic view of metropolitan dominance, one could predict that eventually all hinterland communities will come under the organizing influence of metropolitan centers, although this is not yet the case in the United States. As expressed above, metropolitan centers still compete with the effects of local community conditions, especially in the more remote hinterland areas of the metropolitan region. Hence, in the less metropolitanized geographic divisions of the nation, we should expect to find that local community characteristics which are the result of natural environmental processes are perhaps more influential in determining hinterland inter- community variation than metropolitan centers. As a result, 222 fertility in these communities will be more a product of local community conditions than metropolitan influence. This suggests a sixth hypothesis for testing: 6. In the more metropolitanized geographic divisions, size and distance of a dominating metropolitan cen— ter will be more important in accounting for varia— tion in community fertility behavior, in both urban and rural hinterlands, than local community social structure, when controlling for the influence of metropolitan centers; in less metropolitanized geo- graphic divisions, local community social structure will be more important in accounting for variation in community fertility behavior than size and dis— tance of a dominating metropolitan center. Considering the implications of inter—divisional variation for metropolitan dominance theory greatly expands the number of testable hypotheses and also enables us to consider metropolitan dominance as a dynamic process. We have hypothesized that as metropolitan centers continue to emerge, hinterland community variation will continue to fall more and more under the organizing influence of metropolitan centers. An inter-dependence of metropolitan center and hinterland communities will become the dominant characteris- tic of community organization. But in this dynamic view we must not commit the error of urban dominance theory. We must not think of urban and rural differences as diminishing while metropolitanization increases. An important point of metropolitan dominance theory predicts that differences will increase among hinterland communities under the dominance of the same metropolitan center. Bogue found that in consider- ing inter-regional variation along with the effects of 223 metropolitan dominance on the hinterland that "differences associated with dominance and subdominance within each region are greater than the average differences between . "109 regions. This suggests that as metropolitan centers become more and more the organizing agent of hinterland com- munities in the nation, that the patterns they effect in the hinterlands will appear to be a universal pattern. Divi- sional differences will become less pronounced and differ— ences between hinterland community types (urban and rural) will become more pronounced. Hence, given the fact that fertility is a function of community social structure, as community social structure becomes more and more influenced 'by metropolitan centers, the impact that community social structure has on fertility behavior in urban hinterlands, for example, will be more and more similar in all geographic divisions than its impact on fertility in rural hinterlands within the same geographic division. Metropolitan dominance theory emphasizes the differentiating effect of metropolitan centers on urban and rural hinterland community social structure, and, as a result, on urban and rural fertility behavior. A comparison of inter-divisional differences of the impact of community social structure on fertility behav- ior within the same class of hinterland communities (urban or rural) should reveal fewer differences than an intra- divisional comparison of the impact of community social 109Ibid., p. 61. 224 structure on fertility behavior between different classes of hinterland communities (urban vs. rural). On the basis of these comments a final hypothesis may be formulated: 7. The impact of community social structure and metro— politan dominance on fertility behavior will mani— fest fewer differences when comparing the same type of hinterland communities (urban or rural) on an inter-divisional basis than when comparing different types of hinterland communities (urban vs. rural) on an intra—divisional basis. Summary: Hypotheses Derived from Metropolitan Dominance Theory In this chapter urban dominance theory and metropol- itan dominance theory have been contrasted. It was decided that metropolitan dominance theory was the preferred theo- retical framework from which to develop hypotheses pertain— ing to the explanation of urban-rural fertility differential patterns found in the United States. Seven basic hypotheses were derived and are summarized below. 1. Community social structure is a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. a. Distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will manifest a different impact on com- munity social structure in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. Fertility behavior is a function of community social structure and distance and size of a dominating met- ropolitan center. a. Community social structure and distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will manifest a different impact on fertility behavior in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. Community fertility behavior in both urban and rural hinterlands is not only a function of the size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center, but 225 also a function of conditions of its own immediate locality, since all local communities in the metro- politan region possess some degree of dominance over some portion of the hinterland. 4. Community fertility behavior is more a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan cen- ter in the urban hinterland, but more a function of local community social structure in the rural hinter- land, when distance and size of the dominating metro— politan center are controlled. 5. In the more metropolitan geographic divisions com— pared with the less metropolitan geographic divi- sions, the size and distance of a dominating metro- politan center are more important in accounting for variation in community social structure and fertil- ity behavior in both urban and rural hinterland communities. 6. In the more metropolitan geographic divisions, size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center will be more important in accounting for variation in community fertility behavior, in both urban and rural hinterlands, than local community social structure, when controlling for the influence of metropolitan centers; in less metropolitan geographic divisions, local community social structure will be more impor- tant in accounting for variation in community fertil— ity behavior than size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center. 7. The impact of community social structure and metro— politan dominance on fertility behavior will mani— fest fewer differences when comparing the same type of hinterland communities (urban or rural) on an inter—divisional basis than when comparing different types of hinterland communities (urban vs. rural) on an intra—divisional basis. To test these hypotheses requires an altogether dif- ferent research procedure than employed in most empirical studies of the urban—rural fertility differential. The review of fertility studies contained in Chapter II of this thesis makes this especially clear. Though the empirical propositions established in the previous chapter hint at the 226 possibility of different fertility patterns in urban and rural communities of the United States, these propositions prove to be wholly inadequate to provide further direction in the testing of our theoretical hypotheses derived from metropolitan dominance theory. The theoretical framework of metropolitan dominance, then, has proved fruitful by generating new hypotheses and by extending the study of the urban—rural fertility differential into new areas. All four of the critical guidelines for theory design in the study of differential fertility have been answered in this chapter. Now we must consider the methodological procedures by which to test the theoretical hypotheses as well as the theory of metropolitan dominance itself. CHAPTER IV METHODOLOG ICAL PROCEDURES Seven hypotheses have emerged in our consideration of metropolitan dominance theory, each contributing to a furthering of our understanding of the expected patterns of community fertility behavior and what factors may be opera- tive in determining those patterns. We are now confronted with the task of indicating how these hypotheses are to be tested. First, there appear to be several concepts used in these hypotheses which need to be translated into forms which will lend themselves to statistical testing. In other words, what empirical indices can be employed to reflect community social structure, metropolitan dominance, and community fertility behavior? Our first task, then, is to specify operational definitions for these concepts. Second, after the empirical variables are specified, we should review the statistical techniques which will be applied to the data to test our theoretical hypotheses. Conceptual Framework: Specification of Variables Two broad concepts have been suggested in our theo- retical considerations as possible independent variables which are expected to account for variation in fertility 227 228 behavior: community social structure and metropolitan dominance. The sole dependent variable of the analysis is community fertility behavior. Let us consider how these concepts might be reduced to the form of empirical variables. Community Social Structure A countless number of indicators have been employed in community studies for the purpose of representing commu— nity social structure. As in any study of this nature, variables must be carefully selected with fairly specific reasons in mind as the basis for the selection. For the purposes of this study indicators should be chosen on the basis of whether they can be expected to reflect significant internal characteristics of the organization of a community and whether they can be expected to be of special importance in explaining fertility behavior. In the preceding chapter it was suggested that the broad concept of community social structure should be broken down into four basic categories: urbanization, socio-economic status, wife's opportunities alternative to child-bearing, and demographic structure. It is felt that these categories, though greatly narrowing the range of possible indicators of community social structure, will greatly facilitate the search for empirical measures which should relate significantly to fertility behavior. To reflect the extent of urbanization within a community we should seek some measure of the amount of employment of males in agricultural occupations. Such a measure may be 229 considered a function of the extent of employment in non- agricultural occupations and in this way be considered a possible indicator of the degree of urbanization of a com- munity within a modern society.1 Socio—economic status should be reflected in some measure of educational attain- ment and income level for a community. Wife's opportunities alternative to child-bearing within a given community should be reflected in the amount of employment opportunities for women and the amount of income a woman could obtain from employment. The demographic structure of a community should be represented by some measure of the distribution of women within the reproductive age span. For each of these four categories of community social structure, then, two empir- ical variables were employed and can be specifically defined as follows: Employment in Agricultural Occupations (Urbanization) 1. Percent of the male labor force who are farmers and farm managers. 2. Percent of the male labor force who are farm laborers and farm foremen. Socio—Economic Status 3. Median years of school completed by males and females, age 25 and over. 4. Median family income. lJanet Abu-Lughod, "Urban-Rural Differences as a Function of the Demographic Transition: Egyptian Data and an Analytical Model," American Journal of Sociology, LXIX (March, 1964), 488; Hope Tisdale, "The Process of Urbaniza— tion," Social Forces, XX (March, 1942), 311—16; and P. K. Hatt, N. L. Farr, and E. Weinstein, "Types of Population Balance," American Sociological Review, XX (February, 1950), 14-21. 230 Wife's Alternative Opportunities 5. Median female personal income. 6. Percent of females, age 14 and over, who are employed. Demographic Age Structure 7. Percent of ever—married females, age 15—44, who are age 15—24. 8. Percent of ever-married females, age 15—44, who are age 25—34. It should be noted that, because of the employment of census data in this study, the selection of variables to represent community social structure was limited by the types of information available on census tapes. It is felt, however, that, in spite of this limitation, the selection of adequate variables for the testing of our hypotheses is not hampered severely. It should also be pointed out that each of these variables (with the exception of female employment and income) were computed separately for the urban, rural- nonfarm, and rural-farm parts of every county in the nation. Furthermore, because of the complexities and confusion which could result from considering a fertility analysis for whites and nonwhites combined, it was decided to limit the present study only to the white population of the nation. Hence, each of the community social structure variables specified above apply only to the white population of the residential parts of counties. 231 Metropolitan Dominance Metropolitan dominance is another independent vari- able to be included in accounting for variation in fertility behavior. Because of the theoretical framework employed in this study, the development of a measure of influence ex- erted by metropolitan centers on hinterland communities becomes very crucial. There are several possible measures of metropolitan dominance that could be used, but our theo- retical consideration has suggested that the influence of a dominating metropolitan center on a hinterland community is a function of the distance that community is from the metro- politan center and the size of that center. The construc— tion of such a variable requires the development of some classification scheme by which every county in the nation can be given some numerical designation which would approx- imate the amount of influence exerted on that county popula- tion by a dominating metropolitan center, dependent upon the distance from the metropolitan center and the size of the center combined. We may describe the procedure employed in operationalizing metropolitan dominance in the following manner. It was decided to use the 1960 Census definition of Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas to designate metro- politan centers. By definition . . . SMSA (Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area) is a county or group of contiguous counties which contain at least one city of 50,000 inhabitants or more or "twin cities" with a combined population of at least 232 50,000. In addition to the county, or counties, con- taining such a city or cities, contiguous counties are included in an SMSA if, according to certain criteria, they are essentially integrated with the central city. 2 Each SMSA designated by the 1960 Census was located on a map of the United States which outlined county boundaries. Each SMSA county was assigned a numerical value that was a linear function of the size of its popultaion. This value in- creased by l for each 100,000 population up to a population size of 2 million.3 Thus each SMSA county was assigned a value within a range from 1 to 20. On this basis an SMSA county with a population of 2 million or more was assigned a value of 20, an SMSA of 1 million a value of 10, and an SMSA of 100,000 a value of 1. Any SMSA county with a popu- lation between 50,000 and 100,000 was also given a value of 1. Only whole integer numbers were employed to represent 2U. S. Bureau of the Census, U.S. Census of Populge tion: 1960, Number of Inhabitants, United States Summary, Final Report PC(l)—lA (Washington, D.C.: Government Print— ing Office, 1961), p. xxiv. 3The establishment of a maximum size value of 20 for all SMSA's with populations of 2 million or more is based on the speculation that at some point increases in population are merely duplications of technological functions and condi- tions that exist in areas having maximum population density. Thus, it was arbitrarily decided that any SMSA of 2 million or more population would possess similar technological bases and would exert the same influence over the same size hinter- land area. See Dale Hathaway, J. Allan Beegle, and Keith Bryant, Rural America, Census Monograph, forthcoming, pp. 15- 16. Furthermore, it might be stated that of the 212 SMSA's designated by the 1960 Census, only 10 have a population size of over 2 million: Boston, Chicago, Detroit, Los Angeles, New York, Philadelphia, Pittsburgh, St. Louis, San Francisco-Oakland, and Washington. 233 the size of an SMSA. Hence an SMSA of 150,000 or more was assigned the next highest integer of 2. All counties of a given SMSA were treated as a unit and therefore were all given the same size value. After SMSA counties were located and assigned values based on size, the next task was to assign values to all non—SMSA counties in the nation based on distance from a dominating metropolitan center and the size of that center. After determining a central point for each SMSA (the center of the SMSA county containing the central city), concentric circles were drawn radiating out from each SMSA. The first circle was given a radius of 50 miles, the second circle a radius of 100 miles, the third 150 miles, etc. This created a series of distance bands around each SMSA, each band being 50 miles in width. A county was not con- sidered lying within a given distance band unless completely covered by the most distant boundary of the distance band. Because we assume that metropolitan dominance is related to both distance and size, each county was assigned a numerical value which was a combined function of the size of the influ— encing SMSA and of the distance from the SMSA. Each band, and consequently all counties covered by that band, was assigned a value that declined as a function of the number of 50 mile distance bands from the influencing SMSA. This decline was by a numerical value of 2. As a result all non- SMSA counties within the first 50 mile band from an SMSA were assigned a value 2 less than that assigned to the SMSA 234 county or counties. Non-SMSA counties between 50 to 100 miles of an SMSA were assigned a value 2 less than the value assigned to counties within 50 miles of the SMSA. Hence, in the case of an SMSA of 2 million population, the SMSA coun— ties received a value of 20, non-SMSA counties in the first 50 mile band a value of 18, the second band 16, etc. This procedure was followed until the value zero was reached or a competing SMSA determined the values for such counties. An implication of this scheme is that influence of a metro— politan center becomes negligible when the zero value is reached. Generally the largerthe SMSA in population size, the larger the hinterland area: the smaller the SMSA, the smaller the hinterland area influenced by the metropolitan center. Because of the numerical scheme employed, we assume that a metropolitan center of 2 million or more can extend its influence up to a maximum of 450 miles, though with each distance band its influence is represented as gradually diminishing. SMSA's of smaller size would extend their influence less than this, in proportion to their population size. With this scheme it was possible that a county would receive different values from different SMSA's. It was decided that the final value assigned to any county should always be the highest possible value obtainable through the methodological procedures employed above. Hence, where sev— eral bands overlapped the same non-SMSA county, the county 235 was assigned the highest possible value and allocated to the hinterland of the metropolitan center which determined this value. A further implication of a scheme which recognizes size of a dominating metropolitan center is the possibility that larger SMSA's may influence not only non—SMSA counties within their hinterlands, but also other smaller SMSA's with— in their hinterlands. To distinguish these smaller SMSA's from non-SMSA counties lying within the same distance band from a larger SMSA, it was decided that the value assigned these smaller SMSA's should be the value received from the distance band in which it was located plp§_the size value, determined on the basis of a numerical value of l for every 100,000 population in the smaller SMSA. Hence it was pos— sible that an SMSA of 200,000 (with a size value of 2) lying within a distance band 400 miles from an SMSA of 20 million (receiving a distance value of 4 from that SMSA) could receive a total size-distance score of 6 as the highest pos- sible value it could receive using the methods described above. It had to be assumed, however, that no SMSA county located within the sphere of influence of a larger SMSA could receive a total value (the sum of the size value and the dis— tance value) larger than that assigned to the larger SMSA. .As an example of this rule, suppose a county is designated as an SMSA county with a population of 1,100,000. Its size value is therefore 11. The counties included in the first 236 50 mile band from the SMSA are assigned the value of 9, the second band 7, etc. Suppose that an SMSA county with a pop- ulation of 600,000 is located between 50 and 100 miles from the first SMSA. Using our addition rule, it should receive a distance value of 7 and a size value of 6, or a total value of 13. Since the influencing SMSA could obtain only a value of 11, the value of the smaller SMSA is limited to a value of 11 also. However, this occurred in few cases. By this procedure all counties in the United States were assigned a single numerical value from a possible range of zero to twenty. Highest values reflect the greatest influence from metropolitan centers based on proximity and size, smallest values reflect least influence from metropol- itan centers. All counties assigned the same numerical value are assumed to be equally affected by the organizing. influence of a metropolitan center. Since our analysis required the breakdown of county populations into urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm components, it was decided that each residential component of the same county should receive the same value representing metropolitan influence as assigned the whole county. It should be noted that these values assigned to the residential parts of counties were inserted on the census tapes. All other variables used in the analysis were able to be computed directly from the data included on the census tapes. 237 Community_Fertility_Behavior The dependent variable of this study is community fertility behavior. Numerous measures of fertility behavior have been developed through the years by demographers.4 Though no single measure of fertility can be considered the best overall measure, the choice of a fertility measure depends upon many factors, such as, purpose of the investi- gation and the source and nature of available data. The measure of fertility used in this study is a measure of cumulative fertility which is available on the 1960 Census tapes, the single source of data employed in this study. More specifically the dependent variable can be defined as: the number of white children ever-born to ever—married white females, age 15-44, per 1,000 ever married white females, age 15-44. Similar to all variables in this analysis, only the white population of the nation is considered. Also this 4See discussions of various measures in George W. Barclay, Techniques of Population Analysis (New York: John Wiley, 1958), Ch. 6; John Hajnal, The Study of Fertility and Reproduction: A Survey of Thirty Years," in Thirty Years of Research in Human Fertility: Retrospect and Prospect (New YOrk: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1959), pp. ll-37; N. D. Ryder, "Fertility," in P. M. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Population (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1959), pp. 400-36; Donald J. Bogue and James A. Palmore, "Some Empirical and Analytic Relations among Demographic Fertility Measures, with Regression Models for Fertility Estimation," Demography, I, No. l (1964), 316-38; and Ronald Freedman, "The Sociology of Human Fertility," Current Sociology, X/XI, No. 2 (1961-62), (Oxford, England: Basil Blackwell, 1963), pp. 43-46. . t..:.~\~,.. .C 238 measure is computed for the three residential components of all counties in the nation. The data on children ever born in the 1960 Census arwe based upon a 25 percent sample of the population and are deazrived from answers to the following question on the House— hc>LLxd Questionnaire: "If this is a woman who has ever been Huaz:tried—-How many babies has she ever had, not counting srt;i.illbirths? Do ppp count her stepchildren or adopted chil- Jj~3=7i:hs. It is likely that many of the unwed mothers living M’jL3t3511 an illegitimate child reported themselves as having 13th married. Stepchildren, adopted children, and still— ijL“1:‘i:hs, nevertheless, were not counted in this measure of betility. The measure of fertility used in this study, then, I‘Qb . . n . o J:esents the cumulative fertility of married women until llypppp‘ppp 1:;i‘ 5U. S. Bureau of the Census, U.S. Census of Pppula- EET§3§EEEEi: 1960, Subject Reports, Women by Number of Children Irleéfsil: Born, Final Report PC(2)-3A (Washington, D.C.: Govern- ]:lt: Printing Office, 1964), p. x. 239 the time of the census, i.e., it represents their reproduc- tive histories. One might also consider the measure as the "average number of children" per married woman or "average size of family." It should be noted, however, that this is not a measure of size of "completed family," since the num- ber of children ever born is related to married women still within the reproductive period, ages 15—44. On the other hand, our measure of fertility cannot be likened to a mea— sure of current fertility because past births are considered as well as current births, regardless of the time period in which they occurred. As do all measures of fertility, chil- dren ever born has its advantages and disadvantages. Unlike some measures of fertility, children evern born enumerated in the census are related to the actual group of women who Produced them. In this sense, the children ever born mea- Sure is similar to cohort fertility. Since it is based on c1"‘:i~1l.dren born over a relatively long, unspecified period of time, the cumulative fertility rate will probably not be iI‘ldslmenced greatly by temporal or short—time events, which can affect current fertility measures quite radically. Fun: thermore, mortality should not affect this measure, since a1 1 children ever born are to be recorded, although the mea- sure may suffer from inaccurate reporting because of the 6% bendency upon retrospection by the respondent. Birth Q VQrcounts and undercounts undoubtedly occur, though Grabill, K - a‘S~er and Whelpton, in commenting on the children ever born 240 measure, assert that while overcounts of children ever born inay occur almost as frequently as undercounts, "it is prob- aIDle that the bulk of the reports on children ever born are (:cnnplete and accurate, at least for whites."6 The fact that Inaalrital status is incorporated in our measure of fertility gireaatly refines this measure, although perhaps accounting .ftaczr age at marriage and marital duration would have contrib- iitzesad even more to the development of a better measure of :Eeazzrizility. It is very possible, however, that different Cij_£3wtributions of married women within different age groups C313' 1:he reproductive age span of 15-44 could greatly affect tllilEi fertility level of a given population. That is, a popu- Jréth::icn1Mdth a disproportionately large number of married women in the ages, say, of 15-24 could produce a rather low ‘J‘€3“\7an and rural fertility. Goldstein and Mayer, in consider— J‘Irl5ér tide particular problem, state that "the current place (32:3 residence of the mother does not necessarily indicate the \ 13. 6W. H. Grabill, C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton, The 'nggéisitilipypof American Women (New YOrk: John Wiley, 1958), ‘ 402. 241 residence at the time of birth of children." This resur- :rreax:ts the problem considered previously in this thesis con— cerning the effect of migration on fertility and the diffi- culty of relating community social structure characteristics of current residence to fertility events which may have However, Goldstein occurred previous to current residence. in considering whether suburban fertility mea- and Mayer, S ured as children ever born is a result of current residence conclude that suburban or a selective migration process, fertility is more a function of current residence than a Though such deficiencies may Q onsequence of migration. ‘VV':Ef the complexity that diverse patterns of racial composi- ‘t::i_<3n of communities within different parts of the nation may inflict upon the analysis. Analysis of nonwhite fertility employing the same research design as this study may well be C onsidered a greatly needed but necessarily separate study. An important level of comparison for this study is REZVITLEE comparison of urban and rural fertility patterns. All variables, independent and dependent, are computed on the 71:>iElssis of urban, rural-nonfarm and rural-farm parts of coun- 1t:15_proach suffers especially from the limited number of inde— pemdent variables that can be simultaneously incorporated into an analysis of fertility behavior. The problem of this 1:l‘iesis, then, is how to relate simultaneously to fertility t~11e several variables already presented above, 172E” metro— politan dominance and the various indicators of community SOcial structure, all of which are assumed to have some influence on our dependent variable, community fertility behavior? We not only need some statistical measure of the degree of association of the independent variables to fertil— ity behavior, but we need to know how important these vari- aJDles are in accounting for variation of fertility behavior 246 in comparison with each other. In addition, we should also seek an answer to whether these independent variables have different effects on fertility in urban and rural hinterland corrlrnunities as well as within the different geographic divi- 8 ions. It seems that the most appropriate approach to our problem is a distributive approach and it has been shown by Bog ue and Harris that the distributive approach lends itself Very well to a multiple regression analysis.lo wt iple Regression Model Our analysis focuses on two levels: the nation C Q cnterminous United States) and the nine geographic divi— 3 lens. For the nation and each division a multiple regres- e 2.!ch equation was estimated for the three residential compo- Ehts: urban, rural—nonfarm, and rural-farm. The multiple 1: . . . . . eg’Ic‘eSSion equation may be written in the follOWing general Y = a + blxil = b2X12 + ... + ng19 + ul 1 = l, 2, ...... N j = l, 2, ...... 9 Yi is the ith observed value of the dependent variable; Xij is the ith value of the jth independent variable; \ 10Donald J. Bogue and Dorothy Harris, Comparative ‘g‘9SEZBplation and Urban Research Via Multiple Regression and ‘g‘9~§:§3riance Analysis (Miami, Ohio: Scripps Foundation for SSearch in Population Problems, 1954). ZQLES 247 is the ith random disturbance term. It is assumed that the ui are independent and come from a normal distribution with zero mean and finite variance. is the general constant term. This represents the value of Y which may be expected when each of the independent variables has a value of zero. is the partial regression coefficient of the jpp independent variable. These coefficients show the average effect on Y of one unit change in the accompanying independent variable when allowance has been made for the other independent variables of the equation. :i_n any regression analysis of this sort, it is necessary ‘t1171;511t; the following conditions be assumed for the universe 1321:.<:>IT1 which the data are drawn: (1) the deviations from ITeai‘Ea‘lrz‘ession are normally distributed about the regression; (2) the variance from regression is constant throughout the ant ire range of the independent variables; and (3) the re— g-ression is assumed to be of a linear form. The following \7‘ . . . . . EBLITTLables were inserted in each of the regreSSion equations: The dependent variable: Y'measures the number of children ever born per 1,000 ever-married white females age 15—44 in the residence component of a county in 1960. The independent variables: X l was the value assigned the county by the size- distance measure developed to approximate metro- politan dominance for the residence component of a county in 1960. measures the percent of the white male employed labor force who were farmers and farm managers in the residence component of a county in 1960. measures the percent of the white male employed labor force who were farm laborers and farm foremen in the residence component of a county in 1960. 248 4 measures the median years of school completed by white males and females, age 25 and over, in the residence component of a county in 1960. X5 measures the median white family income in the residence component of a county in 1959. X6 measures the median white female personal income for a county in 1959. X7 measures the percent of white females, age 14 and over, who were employed in the county in 1960. X8 measures the percent of ever-married white females, age 15-44, who were age 15-24 in the residence component of a county in 1960. X9 measures the percent of ever-married white females, age 15-44, who were age 25-34 in the residence component of a county in 1960. In the estimation of each of the prescribed regres- ES jL—<:>Jri equations the following statistics were computed: Si jLJITII;>le correlation coefficients between all variables, the e St imated partial regression coefficients, the estimated Es«b-h-Eat‘ilridard error of the partial regression coefficients, the eaisstlzimated standard partial regression coefficient (also 17% ferred to as beta coefficient or beta weight), the stane (BJE‘JC’d error of estimate, the multiple correlation coefficient, E37r1451 the coefficient of multiple determination. Let us give SSIFJEicial consideration to some of these statistics in terms (unis the nature of the statistic and how it will be employed In the analysis. :EB “~S§Lfii§ Coefficients In the testing of our hypothesis with respect to ‘A? ‘IRHEit.independent variables influence fertility behavior, it 249 _i;;5; inecessary that we be able to come to some conclusion as -t:.<:> 110w important an independent variable is compared with others in its relative ability to produce change in the dependent variable. Partial regression coefficients cannot 1C>Eau1:*1:;ial regression coefficients expressed in standard mea- 53“;13ET t:hat of the dependent variable. The formula used to <:: . . <:>Itlpute beta coeffiCients may be expressed as SX. B. = b. ——l 3 3 5y 1P‘alfiere B. is the beta coefficient of the jth independent 3 variable; b. is the estimated partial regression coefficient 3 of the jth independent variable; 8 is the standard deviation of the jth independent j variable; 8 is the standard deviation of the dependent vari- y able. m. 1‘“: 250 Be ta coefficients are pure numbers which take into account the variation in the independent variable relative to the dependent variable. The beta coefficients are summapy mea- s 1.11: es of the relative importance of an independent variable in accounting for the variation in the dependent variable. The sign of the beta coefficient indicates the direction of the effect. Beta coefficients were estimated for all inde- pendent variables in all equations and are used to compare the independent variables of metropolitan dominance and c OI‘Itur'nunity social structure in their relative importance in de t ermining community fertility levels. gmficient of Multiple Determination In our analysis of differential fertility compari- 8’ one for urban and rural communities, we shall want to know how successful the combined effect of the independent vari- a‘b les is in determining fertility variation. The success of the multiple-variable estimating equation in accounting for the variation in the dependent variable may be summarized by ~Elle coefficient of determination (R2) which is simply the 11111 ltiple correlation coefficient (R) squared. In regression tQIms the square of the correlation coefficient is an esti— rt“ate of the proportion of the variance in the dependent Vériable that is accounted for by the regression of the erendent variable on the independent variables inserted in 1:Iie equat ion . 251 Ze r o—Order Correlation Coefficients Zero—order correlation coefficients (Pearsonian r's) “A71111‘Inunity social structure variables do have a general as S ociation pattern with fertility. However we should also ‘:=‘<:>1:1£3ider the possibility of intercorrelation of our indepen— Gelit: variables to make some assessment as to whether high it‘lrlitlearcorrelation among the independent variables might <51Ii~11121nish the success in accounting for a large portion of itljbl‘st variation in the dependent variable. As Blalock points (:>‘;l1t in.his discussion of multiple correlation, "if we wish it;<:> explain as much variation in the dependent variable as stsible, we should look for independent variables which are IDESVlatively unrelated to each other but which have at least It‘Qderately high correlations with the dependent variable."11 rI“}1.is is an especially difficult task to perform in any socio— ngical research. If high intercorrelations are discovered, \ llHubert M. Blalock, Jr., Social Statistics (New York : McGraw-Hill, 1960), p. 348. 252 we must admit to this deficiency and make some suggestions 23. s to which variables would be more appropriate for explain- ing a larger proportion of fertility behavior for future study.12 Nevertheless, we shall consider zero—order corre— lat; ion only as a preliminary analysis of what factors may influence community fertility behavior and then move on to more rigorous measures of association, measures which will not only account for variation in the dependent variable by a S ingle independent variable alone, but will also hold con— Star-11; the influence that other independent variables may eXert on the dependent variable. _\ \nr 12Intercorrelations among the independent variables care generally low. The highest intercorrelations, of hourse, were found between the paired variables employed to de 1E lect aspects of community social structure, such as, negree of urbanization, socio-economic status, wife's alter- iat ive opportunities, and demographic age structure. Lowest intercorrelations are found for the paired variables reflect— Q g socio—economic status (education and family income) and wimographic age structure (ever-married females, age 15-44, 2L Q were 15—24 or 25—34) . Intercorrelations for family mhqome and education for all divisions and the nation were Qsmly below a value of i.20; intercorrelations for demo- hl: Ephic age structure variables were on the average slightly tatgher, although generally lower than —.30. Intercorrela- tbns among variables reflecting employment in agricultural lQQupations were high in urban and rural—nonfarm areas but QQVV in rural-farm areas for the nine divisions. For urban I: eas zero—order correlations ranged from .32 and .64; gural-nonfarm .24 to .79; rural-farm coefficients were therally below _-l_-_.l4. The most highly correlated paired mfiriables occurred between female income and female employ- WQ ht. The coefficients ranged from .49 to .83. No attempt {\QS made to remove highly correlated variables from the thression equations, though it would appear that overall Ghere are low levels of intercorrelation among the indepen— Qnt variables. 253 Partial Correlation Coefficients Partial correlation coefficients are measures of the degree of relationship between a dependent variable and a S ingle independent variable, controlling for one or more other independent variables. These should not be confused With partial regression coefficients which are mentioned above in our discussion of the multiple regression equation. The formula for computing partial correlation coefficients may be expressed generally as r. . - (r. ) (r. ) rij.k 11 1k 4k 2 \/(l "' rik) (1 - rjk) P a12“I:.ial correlation coefficients will be computed directly fr Om zero—order correlation coefficients. It should be r10ted that the square of the partial correlation coefficient represents the proportion of variation in the virst variable ( Qependent variable) left unexplained by the third variable, but which can be explained by the second variable. Partial QQit‘relation coefficients will be used sparingly in the é‘rlélysis. As an example, we shall want to use partial corre- 3‘ aHtion coefficients to consider the association between com- hzllll-it-xity social structure variables and fertility in urban and rural communities, holding constant the effects of metropol- itan dominance. After considering such data, however, we ghall want to move to more rigorous measures of association Dr‘ovided in the multiple regression analysis. 254 Mu ltiple-Partial Correlation C oe fficients At certain points in the analysis it will be desir— ab le to compute a multiple—partial correlation between a dependent variable and more than one independent variable, controlling for one or more other independent variables. The multiple—partial correlation coefficient has not been use 6 very frequently in sociological research, 13 but it can ]:>eacause the combined effects of independent variables are t:£aJ:k:>sserved (a 100 percent sample) and what the interpretation Es"Iii-(Duld be of these tests of significance when they are 35‘1E3191ied.15 Though we shall follow Bogue and Harris' advice \ 15This seems to be a very common problem confronted UhDEZ’ almost any researcher using demographic data. Bogue and 1E1Eiacris suggest that no tests of significance are needed with E3 ILOO percent sample if there is no attempt to generalize to .larger universe in time or space. See Donald Bogue and erothy Harris, op. cit., p. 12. Hagood and Price suggest }1Ert such total populations be considered as "samples from‘ EstZilllarger hypothetical universes of possibilities." See ailr'garet J. Hagood and Daniel 0. Price, Statistics for Soci- JElebgists (Rev. ed.; New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, J~S15Q), pp. 286-94. Selvin points out, however, that one must 63c:ognize that sampling error is only one type of random €321i‘Ilz‘or. "Even where there is no sampling in the usual sense, 257 and not wish to generalize the findings of this study to a larger universe than for the counties of the nation in 1960, we shall proceed to apply tests of significance for the statistics employed in this study due to possible random error in response and processing as well as in sampling, erince the census data employed in this study were collected (>11 the basis of a 25 percent sample. However, it should be eezrqohasized that the main concern of this thesis is locating eaLrlci partitioning sources of variation in a dependent vari- aafll:>.lxe, hence the use of correlation statistics. Tests of S ignificance are of minor importance and will be used only 't:<::> Iirge caution when small statistical differences are dis- c—‘—C>\7ered. The "t" test was used to ascertain whether zero— ‘:’3=:‘rn zero. The chosen level of significance was .05. The S t a tistic has "Student's" distribution with N-2 degrees of freedom. \ d‘:L'S<:repancies between the true situation and the observed €25Sults may be produced by random errors of response or - ITCDCessing. It might seem, therefore, that tests of signif- tqance could be used to compare total populations, if the 62551:5 are interpreted as dealing with random errors of QeSponse or processing." See Hanan C. Selvin, "A Critique $3:ff Trests of Significance in Survey Research," American '-JEEE§iological Review, XXII (October, 1957), 525. 258 The "F" test was used to determine the significance of the partial correlation coefficients, multiple—partial correlation coefficients, and multiple correlation coeffi— cients. With respect to partial correlation coefficients we txasted the hypothesis that the coefficient was significantly CLifferent from zero at the .05 level. The general formula for testing the partial rij.kl 18 2 r.. 1].}(1 (N _ k _ l) Fl,N—k—l = 1 _ r2 ij.kl Where the total number of variables is k + l and N is the t24C2>tzzal number of observations. This same formula may also be 1.18 e <1 to test whether the multiple-partial correlation coef- ff-ji——<:=:ient is significantly different from zero. The .05 level of significance is used in this test also. The general :EE<:3fiI?Inula employed to test the null hypothesis that the multi- I;>:1~€3: correlation coefficient (R) is not significantly differ— eailfil‘: from zero may be expressed as Fk,N—k—l = 1 R2 k VVIIEire k represents the number of independent variables and 1S: tihe number of observations. The "t" test was also used to ascertain whether the eesstlimated regression coefficients were significantly differ— earltl from zero. Again the level of significance chosen was t:}1€3 .05 level. The form of the "t" test used was CL nos § » 259 b. - O t = _J_____ Sb. 3 which has N — k — 1 degrees of freedom and where b. is the estimated partial regression coefficient of 3 the jth independent variable; 5b is the estimated standard deviation of bj. j A final statistical test, the multiple comparison tzeast, was employed to determine whether there were differ— ences in the effects of the independent variables on the dependent variable between residential parts of counties (’;i4ritra-divisional) and between geographic divisions (inter— dii:igxifiisional) for the same residential parts of counties. iTIIfiL;i_ss involves testing the equality of partial regression C! (De fficients between the various multiple regression equa— t.jL.<::uras. The question which is asked in this test is whether ‘t171:::1m; k a. nd 1221 SSUk of variable Xj in the k equations. the estimated partial regression coefficient of in the equation k (k = l,....,u,....,v,.....k); l the jth diagonal element of the (X'X)— matrix equation k; the sum of squares of residuals from equation k; the degrees of freedom from equation k (Qk = - p , when N is the number of observations and the number of parameters in equation k). H: B‘?-BY=0 O J 3 1.1 V Han—B- O, l J 37, = SSU. the test statistic SSDuV / (k — l) k SSU / Z Qk k=l \ C>:L. l6See K. A. Brownlee, Statistical Theory and Method- TTE§SE§SEIy in Science and Engineering (New York: John Wiley, 0), pp. 3l6ff. 261 k follows the 13‘ distribution with k - l and Z Qk degrees of k=l freedom. The chosen level of significance of the test was .05. One assumption which must be met for the test to be valid is that the residual variances in the k equations be equal; that is, This chapter has presented a discussion of the con— <::eaptual and the statistical frameworks employed in this 1:.Ijfiesis., Concepts from the theoretical framework were trans- ;1f}:>n:med.into empirical measures, each based on an interval S cale. Also discussed have been the multiple regression nr1<:>£at:terns for the nation and the geographic divisions of the Jrlnait:ion is metropolitan dominance theory. The basic proposi— ‘tZL:i.c>n running through this study is that different patterns <:>:1E’ urban and rural fertility variation are associated with “t: ITL:13: ihinterland communities. The test of differential urban and rural fertility patterns, then, is also a test of metro- I=:><:>-:‘Litandominance theory in general. The organization of this chapter will be provided by the seven hypotheses. Each I‘r“":.2":E.:>-::>thesis will be individually introduced followed by a Dre Sentation and discussion of the types of data available jET:?<:’ITI our regression analyses which are most relevant to the t: e S t ing of the particular hypothesis. B1 - W Community social structure is a function of distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. 262 -¥ 263 a. Distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will manifest a different impact on community social structures in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. To test this hypothesis we shall consider the zero— order correlation coefficients which reflect the degree and direction of association between metropolitan dominance and 'the various indices of community social structure. If metro— Exolitan centers are organizing agents of their respective lefban and rural hinterlands, we should expect to find signif— .j_c:ant correlations between distance from metropolitan cen- 1::€31:s by size and community social structure characteristics. 51?.53131e 17 presents the zero-order correlation coefficients :E?<:>J: metropolitan dominance and employment in agricultural C:><::<::upations, measures which are assumed to reflect urbaniza- ‘t: :i.<:>n. Generally the coefficients are rather moderate in 53 :i_:2:e. Overall there appears to be a negative correlation of ‘fiujLuSS'tance from metropolitan centers by size and employment in E‘-<:’:L—:Lctan centers seem to have more of an influence on employ— Mel—1t of farmers and farm managers than on farm laborers and fs<:xtr‘531nen. In comparing urban and rural areas, there appears to be 1. . . . . . . ittle difference in direction of assoc1ation, however, Vv.1“;1'1 respect to degree of association correlations of farm- 62 a: 53' and farm managers seem to be slightly higher in the 264 Table 17. Zero—order correlation of metropolitan dominance and employment in agricultural occupations (urbanization) for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Metropolitan Domi— Metropolitan nance and Farmers Dominance and Farm and Farm Managers Laborers and Foremen (Zonterminous IJnited States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF 51nd DiViSions r12 r12 r12 r13 r13 r13 (JIQITED STATES —.348* —.390* —.287* -.218* -.273* -.133* .ISTeavvjEngland —.376* —.401* —.399* —.368* -.407* -.288* lxflfljicidle Atlantic -.l76* —.372* —.428* —.378* —.392* -.287* .12: .. N) Central -.ll6* —.ll9* -.207* —.151* -.122* —.096 1797 .. N. Central -.387* -.484* -.609* —.292* -.276* -.219* :E; <:>NL1th Atlantic —.309* -.219* —.127* -.l9l* -.158* .045 E - s. Central -.095 -.014 .160* .112 .052 .174* 5‘7 .. £3. Central —.322* -.089 —.272* -.273* -.26l* -.283* D1;111tain —.249* -.246* -.205* -.189* -.100 .021 Pacific -.094 -.253* —.429* -.025 .087 .211* \ *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. 11153 X Metropolitan dominance (distance and size of t :I: opolifan center) . if Eadtrltlers X Percent of male and farm managers. labor force who are employed as X Percent of male labor force who are employed as if arm lab 3 orers and foremen. 265 rural hinterland than the urban. In West North Central, e.g., 37 percent of the variation in employment of farmers and farm managers is explained by metropolitan dominance among rural—farm communities, 23 percent among rural-nonfarm communities, but only 15 percent among urban hinterland com— munities. This pattern persists also for five other divi— sions, especially the more metropolitan ones. For employ— ment of farm laborers and foremen correlations are much lower and there appears to be a reversal of pattern in terms of the significance of metropolitan dominance in determining the pattern of variation among urban and rural hinterland communities, i.e., coefficients appear highest in urban areas. Table 18 provides the zero—order correlation coeffi- cients between metropolitan dominance and socio-economic status characteristics of urban and rural hinterland commu— nities. The coefficients for education are surprisingly low, suggesting that metropolitan centers have little influence on education levels of hinterland communities, although coeffi- cients tend to be higher among both rural-nonfarm and rural— farm communities than among urban. The direction of associa— tion is not consistent among the divisions, although for rural-nonfarm areas the greater tendency is for educational levels of communities to increase as one approaches metro- politan centers. 266 Table 18. Zero-order correlation of metropolitan dominance and socio—economic status for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Metropolitan Metropolitan Dominance and Dominance and Education Family Income Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions 414 r14 r14 r15 r15 r15 UNITED STATES —.046* .075* —.046* .414* .472* .408* New England -.127 .286* .283* .812* .772* .705* Middle Atlantic —.035 .299* -.075 .297* .098 .364* E. N. Central .105 .359* .194* .015 .043 -.026 W. N. Central -.296* -.258* -.306* -.109* .312* -.017 South Atlantic -.017 .095* .063 .703* .744* .706* E. S. Central -.375* —.266* —.294* —.312* —.045 .362* W. S. Central .071 -.181* -.329* .107 —.020 .001 Mountain .161* .200* —.039 .283* -.094 -.074 Pacific .053 .107 —.l60 .668* .636* .652* * Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. X Metropolitan dominance (distance and size of met— ropolitan center). X Median years of school completed by males and females, X5 Median family income in 1959. age 25 and over. 267 Of all the measures of community social structure employed in this study, metropolitan centers seem to have the greatest influence on family income levels in both urban and rural hinterland communities, when comparing zero-order correlation coefficients. The direction of association in most cases is positive so that the greater the proximity of a community to a metropolitan center, the higher will be its composite level of family income. There is a high positive correlation of metropolitan dominance and family income for New England, South Atlantic, and Pacific divisions, but among these there is no consistent pattern as to whether in the urban or rural hinterland metropolitan dominance has more influence in determining family income. Table 19 considers the influence of metropolitan dominance on wife's alternative opportunities in a community. Female personal income is generally positively related to distance from metropolitan centers by size. Female employ- ment reflects the same association pattern although the direction of association is more mixed. Correlation coeffi— cients are relatively low, although metropolitan dominance seems to influence female personal income levels more than the female employment rate. In the comparison of urban and rural hinterland communities, nationally metropolitan domi- nance is relatively more important in accounting for female personal income and female employment levels in urban areas than rural, though among divisions this pattern is mixed. Table 19 . Conterxin United 3: and Divis \ 3:11:23 8': 1' . 268 Table 19. Zero-order correlation of metropolitan dominance and wife's alternative opportunities for contermi- nous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of‘ Metropolitan Domi— Metropolitan nance and Female Dominance and Personal Income Female Employment Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions r16 r16 r16 r17 r17 r17 UNITED STATES .232* .191* .195* .177* —.l3l* .139* New England .352* .373* .457* .350* .379* .413* Middle Atlantic -.094 —.218* -.227* .051 -.024 -.067 E. N. Central .155* .143* .105* .217* .241* .183* W. N. Central .258* .266* .277* .048 .037 .069 South Atlantic .067 -.203* —.223* —.033 -.l77* -.182* E. S. Central -.069 —.066 -.078 -.157* —.209* -.192* W. S. Central .237* .204* .200* .061 —.017 -.004 Mountain .478* .382* .215* .418* .331* .209* Pacific .301* .240* .277* .177 .135 .161 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. X Metropolitan dominance (distance and size of met- ropolitan center). X Median female personal income in 1959. 2 X3 Percent females, age 14 and over, who are employed. In New I for 2]- E of femal cent f0I jivisior :iominanc farm c3: 001212311: r '3 " 269 In New England, for example, metropolitan dominance accounts for 21 percent of variation in female income and 17 percent of female employment in rural-farm communities, but 12 per- cent for both cases in urban communities. For the Mountain division percent of variation accounted for by metropolitan dominance is greater for urban than rural—farm or rural non— farm communities. Table 20 portrays the relationship of metropolitan dominance to the demographic age structure of women in the reproductive age span of urban and rural hinterland commu- nities. Distance from a metropolitan center by size is generally negatively associated with ever-married females ages 15—24 but the pattern is mixed for ever-married females ages 25-34. Metropolitan dominance nationally is more influ— ential in determining the distribution of females ages 15—24 in urban communities than rural, especially in the more metropolitan divisions, but for females ages 25—34 the influence of metropolitan dominance is rather insignificant. In summarizing these tables we might conclude that community social structure is only slightly a function of metropolitan dominance. The amount of variation in commu— nity social structure characteristics accounted for by distance from metropolitan centers by size is highest for family income, employment of farmers and farm managers, and ever-married females ages 15-24. Family income is positively associated with metropolitan dominance while employment of farmers and farm managers and ever—married females ages Table 20 H Comte mi: United S t and Divis \ DEED s: 270 Table 20. Zero—order correlation of metropolitan dominance and demographic age structure for onterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Metropolitan Metropolitan Dominance and Dominance and Females, Ages 15—24 Females, Ages 25-34 Conterminous United States Urb . RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions r18 r18 r18 r19 r19 r19 UNITED STATES —.320 -.241 —.127 .004 .081 —.095 New England —.447 —.697 -.268 -.201 .306 .002 Middle Atlantic —.522 -.511 -.219 .356 .162 -.082 E. N. Central -.159 —.152 .025 .152 .127 -.015 W. N. Central —.076 .103 —.134 -.067 -.097 —.377 South Atlantic —.l65 —.297 —.005 .039 .094 .047 E. S. Central .011 —.001 .125 —.088 -.054 —.096 W. S. Central —.042 —.081 -.l73 -.065 .025 —.121 Mountain —.172 —.087 .139 .061 .020 -.139 Pacific -.333 -.144 -.008 .157 -.066 -.104 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. X Metropolitan dominance (distance and size of met- ropolitan center). ages 15—44, who are X8 Percent ever—married females, age 15-24. ages 15-44, who are X9 Percent ever-married females, age 25-34. 271 15—24 are negatively associated. We cannot conclude that metropolitan centers have a more determinative influence on any single broad dimension of community social structure, such as employment in agricultural occupations, socio- economic status, wife's alternative opportunities, or demo- graphic age structure, since in each of these pairs of vari- ables one of the variables stands above the other in terms of its degree of association with metropolitan dominance. The data included in these tables have suggested only slight differences in the impact of metropolitan dominance on urban vs. rural community social structures. For employment of farmers and farm managers and education, metropolitan dom— inance seems to be more influential in rural communities, but for female personal income and ever—married females ages 15-24, metropolitan dominance seems to be more impor- tant in urban communities. However, the more obvious con- clusion from the zero-order correlation coefficients seems to be the similarity of impact that metropolitan dominance exerts on urban and rural communities. In other words, among the various divisions, where coefficients were rela— tively large, they were large for both urban and rural areas, and where low or nonsignificant, they were for both urban and rural communities. This pattern also is true when con— sidering the direction of association. Generally the data suggest that the influence of metropolitan centers is not as pervasive as one might expect from the theory. This suggests politan conditi cially Eveothe 272 further that additional factors to be considered are differ- ences among the divisions due to differential rates of metro— politanization as well as the influence of local community conditions in determining urban and rural patterns, espe- cially differential fertility patterns. Hypothesis 2 Fertility behavior is a function of community social structure and distance and size of a dominating metro- politan center. a. Community social structure and distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center will manifest a different impact on fertility behavior in the urban hinterland than in the rural hinterland. To test this hypothesis let us consider again zero— order correlation coefficients, but we shift to a considera- tion of fertility as the dependent variable. Is community fertility behavior a function of both metropolitan dominance and community social structure, regardless of whether commu- nity social structure is a reflection of metropolitan domi— nance or its own local environment? In considering this hypothesis we are interested in the existence and direction of association of fertility with metropolitan dominance and community social structure indices as well as the impact or importance each independent variable represents in account— ing for intercommunity variation of fertility levels in urban and rural hinterlands. Table 21 offers the zero—order correlation coeffi- cients of fertility and metropolitan dominance for each dhdsion H I 4 l ropolit. 273 Table 21. Zero-order correlation of fertility and metropol— itan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: Correlation of Fertility and Metropolitan Dominance Conterminous United Urb RNF RF States and Divisions rY1 rYl rYl UNITED STATES -.211* -.268* -.l60* New England —.490* —.676* —.451* Middle Atlantic -.397* -.539* —.394* East North Central -.285* —.319* —.247* West North Central -.255* -.l65* —.l94* South Atlantic —.264* -.213* -.182* East South Central —.038 —.O3l -.047 West South Central —.294* -.122* -.014 Mountain -.309* -.372* -.159* Pacific -.426* -.395* -.275* *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Metropolitan dominance (distance and size of met- ropolitan center). 274 and the nation. All divisions with the exception of East South Central indicate the existence of a significant asso- ciation of fertility and metropolitan dominance. In all cases, urban and rural fertility is negatively related to distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. Especially in the more metropolitan divisions metropolitan dominance is significant in accounting for fertility varia- tion. In New England, for example, 24 percent of fertility variation among urban communities is accounted for by metro— politan dominance, 46 percent among rural—nonfarm, and 20 percent among rural-farm communities. Lowest coefficients appear in the least metropolitan divisions such as East and West South Central. Unexpectedly, while urban correlation coefficients for the most part exceed rural-farm coeffi- cients, the rural-nonfarm sector reflects a tendency to exceed the other two sectors. There is enough evidence to suggest that metropolitan dominance does have a differential impact on fertility among the different types of residential hinterland communities, though the direction of association is the same throughout and the predominance of rural-nonfarm coefficients is unexpected. Table 22 contains the zero-order correlation coeffi- cients for fertility and employment in agricultural occupa— tixbns. Looking first at the association between fertility arnfl employment of farmers and farm managers, slightly over hallf the coefficients are significant in the residential hirl'terlands. The direction of association among the 275 Table 22. Zero—order correlation of fertility and employment in agricultural occupations (urbanization) for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of 'Fertility' ' errtility and Farmers _" '“2 and Farm and Farm Managers Laborers and Foremen Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions rY2 rY2 rY2 rY3 rY3 rY3 UNITED STATES .200* .172* .007 .358* .298* .129* New England .149 .504* .463* .407* .674* .407* Middle Atlantic .095 .236* .103 .143 .291* .255* E. N. Central —.013 -.129* -.127* -.061 -.026 .185* W. N. Central .139* .076 .083 .074 .045 .269* South Atlantic .201* .166* —.139* .216* .229* .066 E. S. Central —.050 —.028 -.314* —.l76* .131* .081 W. S. Central .179* -.025 —.254* .654* .524* .126* Mountain .340* .303* —.166* .216* .220* -.108 Pacific .347* .087 -.097 .307* .282* —.097 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Percent of male labor force who are employed as .farners and farm managers. X Percent of male labor force who are employed as farm laborers and foremen. 276 significant coefficients of urban areas tends toward the positive while in rural areas, especially the rural-farm, the relationship tends toward the negative among the sig- nificant coefficients. We might make reference here to Table 15 (in Chapter II) which summarized the expected relationships of fertility to the independent variables established on the basis of previous research on differen- tial fertility. This table proposed an inverse association in rural areas and a nonsignificant association in urban areas, but our findings suggest the greater contrast of negative in the rural and positive in the urban. It does hold, however, that correlation coefficients are larger in the rural communities, suggesting that employment of farmers and farm managers is more determinant of rural than urban fertility levels. With respect to employment of farm laborers and foremen, on the basis of the empirical propositions estab- lished in Table 15 of Chapter II, it was expected that it be positively associated with fertility in rural areas but non- significant in urban areas. Only three of the urban coeffi- cients are nonsignificant, however, whereas four of the rural-farm coefficients are nonsignificant. According to the data of Table 22 the positive relationship holds gener— Eilly in both urban and rural areas. However in the North- euastern and North Central divisions the rural coefficients 53133 larger than urban, but for the divisions in the South 277 and West the urban coefficients appear to be more important in accounting for fertility variation. For example, employ— ment of farm laborers and foremen accounts for 17 percent of rural-farm fertility, 45 percent of rural—nonfarm and 17 per- cent of urban in New England, but in the West South Central fertility variation is accounted for by this independent variable 43 percent in urban communities, 27 percent rural— nonfarm, and only 2 percent rural—farm. On the basis of these findings we conclude that employment in agricultural occupations as an index of community social structure does have a different impact on fertility in urban than in rural hinterlands, though the pattern is not consistent for farm laborers and foremen. In Table 23 are given the values for the zero-order correlation coefficients for fertility and socio-economic status. Education is for the most part negatively corre— lated with fertility, although moreso in the rural residen- tial areas than urban. Education is not a significant pre- dictor of fertility levels in all residential sectors of the Middle Atlantic division. For the urban hinterland of the more metropolitan divisions, i.e., New England, Middle Atlantic, and East North Central, the coefficients are .positive and nonsignificant. Generally education is more iJifluential in determining fertility levels in the rural hinterland communities, except in the case of the West South (Zenntral and Mountain divisions where education accounts for U Contez United and Di .1 ‘ . Pacific 278 Table 23. Zero-order correlation of fertility and socio— economic status for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of 'Fertility >Fertility ‘ ' and ’ ' and: ‘ Education Family Income Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DlVlSlonS rY4 rY4 rY4 rY5 rY5 rY5 UNITED STATES -.l77* -.236* —.159* —.032 —.052* .042* New England .095 —.443* —.247 -.473* -.666* -.443* Middle Atlantic .092 -.160 .014 —.272* -.037 -.l37 E. N. Central .027 —.272* —.426* .279* -.272* -.234* W. N. Central -.086 -.222* -.318* —.283* -.216* —.091* South Atlantic —.263* —.395* -.274* —.265* -.059 -.043 E. S. Central -.l62* -.374* —.222* -.024 -.169* -.027 W. S. Central —.621* -.528* —.464* .017 —.095* -.289* Mountain -.507* -.455* .013 .047 -.230* .064 Pacific -.434* —.586* -.294* —.311* —.318* -.353* *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Median years of school completed by males and females, X Median family income in 1959. 5 age 25 and over. 279 39 percent and 26 percent of fertility variation in the urban hinterland communities. These findings are in general agreement with the empirical propositions established in Chapter II in terms of direction of association and differen— tial impact of the importance of education in accounting for fertility level variation in rural and urban areas. Family income, the second index of socio—economic status of communities, is also negatively associated with fertility, although moreso in rural than urban areas. Family income is especially significantly related to fertil- ity in the more metropolitan divisions. The empirical prop- ositions from Chapter II relating to this variable suggested the possibility of a positive association of family income and fertility in the urban hinterland, but this is not sup— ported by the zero—order correlation coefficient presented here. Furthermore, on the basis of the empirical proposi- tions established in Chapter II, it was expected that family income coefficients would be higher in urban than rural sec- tors, but this is supported only in the case of four divi— sions: Middle Atlantic, East North Central, West North Central and South Atlantic. Hence the differential impact of family income on urban and rural fertility is not as Clear as education. Family income appears to be a better Eiredictor of fertility levels in the urban hinterlands of tile more metropolitan divisions and education a better pre- Ciixztor in the urban hinterlands of the less metropolitan (iii\fisions, while both education and family income are 280 moderate predictors of fertility in the rural sectors of most divisions, education being relatively more important than family income. Correlation coefficients of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities are listed in Table 24. In the case of both female personal income and female employment there is a negative association with fertility. This is again in agreement with the empirical propositions of Chapter II. It was expected, however, since working women is more an urban characteristic than rural, that the indices of wife's alternative opportunities would be nonsignificant in rural areas but significant in urban areas. With respect to female personal income this does not appear to be the case except for Middle Atlantic. Generally the coefficients indicate that female personal income is significantly re- lated to fertility in all residential sectors. In six divisions, however, female personal income in the urban hinterland does exceed either of the rural hinterlands in accounting for variation in fertility and they are Middle Atlantic, West North Central, South Atlantic, West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific. Hence one might argue that the impact of female personal income on fertility is slightly different, i.e., greater, in the urban hinterland than the Ifilral. In the case of female employment, on the other hand, ififive of the rural-farm coefficients among the divisions are nOnsignificant and, hence, concur with the empirical Table II 281 Table 24. Zero-order correlation of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of -‘Fertility‘T -Fertility t: and Female .7 and: - Personal Income Female Employment Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions rY6 rY6 rY6 rY7 rY7 rY7 UNITED STATES —.269* -.245* —.l72* -.210* —.301* -.l63* New England -.248 —.490* —.4l7* -.231 —.388* -.252 Middle Atlantic -.286* —.097 -.011 —.239* -.235* -.008 E. N. Central —.l95* -.229* -.134* —.088 -.182* -.039 W. N. Central -.387* -.150* —.244* -.l72* -.044 -.036 South Atlantic -.301* —.233* -.131* —.227* -.355* —.183* E. S. Central -.185* -.208* -.199* -.320* -.510* -.413* W. S. Central —.288* -.l69* -.l96* -.157* -.l94* -.205* Mountain —.458* —.343* —.l99* -.522* -.466* -.237* Pacific —.454* —.201* —.066 -.240* -.133 —.063 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Median female personal income in 1959. 6 X Percent females, 7 age 14 and over, who are employed. .D 282 propositions of Chapter II. West North Central and Pacific reveal both rural-farm and rural-nonfarm coefficients as nonsignificant. However female employment does not appear to be as important in predicting urban fertility as expected. Furthermore female employment in rural-nonfarm hinterland communities often reveals a greater amount of fertility variation eXplained than in urban communities. While there is indication of a differential impact of female personal income on urban and rural fertility, female employment does not suggest a clear pattern. Table 25 contains the zero—order correlation coef— ficients of fertility and demographic age distribution of women in the child—bearing period. Generally the tendency is toward a negative association of fertility and the prev- alence of ever-married females ages 15-24 and a positive association of fertility and ever—married females ages 25—34. This concurs with the empirical propositions of Chapter II. With respect to ever-married females ages 15-24 there seem to be exceptions to the expectation that it would be a better predictor of fertility levels in the urban than the rural hinterland, and these exceptions appear in three highly metropolitanized divisions: New England, Middle .Atlantic, and Pacific. In these three divisions the urban Cnaefficient is not significant. Generally, however, females aEJes 15-24 is more frequently a significant variable in (iertermining fertility levels for urban than rural areas. TI'1O'Ugh most of the coefficients for ever—married females 283 Table 25. Zero-order correlation of fertility and demo— graphic age structure for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of ’ Fertility . “Fertility‘ . .,.and " -* p and;.;-’ Females, Ages 15-24 Females, Ages 25—34 Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DiViSions rY8 rY8 rY8 rY9 rY9 rY9 UNITED STATES -.271* —.055* -.ll3* .203* —.004 .110* New England .106 .619* -.073 .190 —.244* .065 Middle Atlantic .081 .308* .073 .032 —.l63 -.016 E. N. Central —.455* -.125* —.269* .129* .021 .028 W. N. Central -.478* —.269* —.l33* .238* .110* .155* South Atlantic —.290* -.027 —.069 .169* —.ll6* .089 E. S. Central -.454* -.039 —.019 .174* —.101 -.009 W. S. Central -.282* —.042 ..051 .349* .133* .036 Mountain —.291* —.074 —.368* .047 -.009 .036 Pacific -.127 -.044 -.l99* .164 .070 .023 *Significantly different from zero at Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X8 Percent ever—married females, ages age 15-24. X9 age 25—34. Percent ever—married females, ages the .05 level. 15—44, who are 15-44, who are 284 ages 25—34 are relatively small and especially nonsignifi— cant in the rural hinterlands, the pattern seems to be a positive relationship to fertility in the urban hinterlands and a positive but nonsignificant relationship in the rural sectors. These coefficients seem to support the expecta- tions based on the empirical propositions of Chapter II with ever-married females ages 25—34 accounting for more of urban fertility variation than rural. It is not as significant a variable, however, as the prevalence of ever-married females ages 15-24. The differential impact of demographic age structure on urban and rural fertility is not clear. These variables, however, are more significant in urban hinter- lands than rural in determining fertility levels. Before proceeding to a consideration of additional data let us summarize what has been discovered to this point. With respect to metropolitan dominance there is a consis— tently significant negative association with fertility. It is especially important in the more metropolitan divisions. A differential impact on urban and rural fertility is sup— ported, in that urban coefficients exceed rural-farm, but rural—nonfarm coefficients were found to exceed both. With respect to employment in agricultural occupations, farmers and farm managers are negatively correlated with fertility in rural areas but positively in urban areas. The differen— tial impact hypothesis is supported in direction of associa- tion and importance of the variable in that rural coefficients excee assoc the s secto: the V5 status ciated nities the fac Family the mgr are lar Opportu; ment are rural CC on urban to exCee 285 exceed urban. Farm laborers and foremen are positively associated with fertility in urban and rural communities and the size of coefficients vary randomly among the residential sectors which suggests no consistent difference in impact of the variable on fertility. Both measures of socio—economic status, education and family income, are negatively asso- ciated with fertility, moreso among rural than urban commu- nities. A differential impact of education is supported by the fact that coefficients are larger in rural areas. Family income reflects a differential impact on fertility in the more metropolitan divisions in that urban coefficients are larger than rural. With respect to wife's alternative opportunities both female personal income and female employ- ment are negatively associated with fertility for urban and rural communities. Female income has a differential impact on urban and rural fertility in that urban coefficients tend to exceed rural. For female employment, however, the differ- ential impact is not clear. Urban coefficients exceed rural- farm coefficients, which are mostly nonsignificant, but highest coefficients appear for rural-nonfarm communities. Finally considering the demographic age structure of commu- nities, the prevalence of ever-married females ages 15-24 is negatively related to fertility but for those ages 25-34 there is a positive association. The differential impact of ever-married females ages 15—24 on urban and rural fertility is partially supported by the occurrence of higher coeffi— Cients in urban areas, but mostly for the less metropolitan divisi< divisi< are qui Variable existenC 286 divisions. Urban coefficients of the more metropolitan divisions are significant but coefficients in rural areas are quite frequently nonsignificant. Ever-married females ages 25-34 reflects a clearer pattern of differential impact on fertility in that the urban coefficients exceed the rural. To conclude this summary it is asserted that fertility is a function of metropolitan dominance and community social structure. For the most part many of the empirical proposi— tions established in Chapter II were supported. Differen- tial impact of the independent variables on fertility by residential type of hinterland, as suggested already in Chapter II, is to be discovered more in the importance of variables in accounting for fertility variation than in the existence or direction of association. To further test the hypothesis of the existence of an association and a differential impact of community sOcial structure and metropolitan dominance on fertility, let us consider coefficients of multiple determination (R2) which will demonstrate the relative importance of the combined effects of the independent variables on fertility. We shall review only the total correlation of the combined effects of all independent variables on fertility. Table 26 diSplays the coefficients of multiple deter- mination which indicate the amount of variation explained in fertility by all independent variables, metropolitan dominance and community social structure. In all cases the coefficient Table 26. 287 Coefficients of multiple determination (R2) of fertility and variables in multiple regression equations for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 R2 Y.123456789 Conterminous United States and Divisions Urb RNF RF UNITED STATES .3376* .2715* .1657* New England .4588* .7307* .4548* Middle Atlantic .3751* .3832* .2297* East North Central .4097* .2815* .3597* West North Central .4212* .1912* .3325* South Atlantic .3966* .3634* .2017* East South Central .3409* .3955* .3389* West South Central .6598* .4687* .3433* Mountain .5738* .4237* .2653* Pacific .6270* .5728* .3064* Average Value .4736 .4234 .3136 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. 288 is significantly different from zero. For urban hinterlands among the divisions the amount of variation accounted for by the independent variables ranges from a low of 34 percent for East South Central to a high of 60 percent for West South Central. For the rural-nonfarm sector the range is from a low of 19 percent to a high of 73 percent for West North Central and New England, respectively. The range in the rural—farm sector is from a low of 20 percent in South Atlantic to a high of 45 percent in New England. Nationally the independent variables account for more variation in fer- tility levels among urban communities than rural—farm, with rural-nonfarm intermediate. If we consider the average values of the coefficients among the divisions the pattern remains the same, with urban coefficients explaining an average of 47 percent of the variation in fertility, rural— nonfarm 42 percent, and rural-farm only 32 percent. The combined effects of the independent variables on fertility is in all divisions greater in the urban sector than the rural-farm. This suggests that fertility is a function of community social structure and metropolitan dominance com- bined and that these factors exert different effects on urban fertility than rural—farm fertility. But the rural- nonfarm coefficients are not consistently intermediate between urban and rural-nonfarm. The coefficient of multi— ple determination in the rural-nonfarm sector exceeds the urban coefficient in three divisions: New England, Middle an N: u L v“ ,,r~ 289 Atlantic, and East South Central. More frequently, however, the rural—nonfarm coefficient is less than the urban. Hence with some reservation, it is concluded that the hypothesis of a differential effect by the independent variables on urban and rural fertility is supported. Hypothesis 3 Community fertility behavior in both urban and rural hinterlands is not only a function of the size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center, but also a function of conditions of its own immediate locality, since all local communities in the metropolitan region possess some degree of dominance over some portion of the hinterland. In order to test this hypothesis what is required is to determine the direction and degree of association between fertility and the various indices of community social struc- ture, holding constant the influence of metrgpolitan domi— nance. In other words, if fertility continues to be signif- icantly related to community social structure variables after the influence of a dominating metropolitan center has been controlled, then we must conclude that this hypothesis is supported. It is assumed, of course, that the associa- tion of fertility and the indices of community social struc- ture, after partialling out the effects that may be due to metropolitan dominance, is a reflection of the influence of local community conditions alone. The types of statistics Which can be employed to test this hypothesis are (1) first- order partial correlation coefficients for fertility and the Various indices of community social structure controlling for 290 distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center and (2) multiple—partial correlation coefficients for fertility and combinations of the variables reflecting community social structure again controlling for metropolitan dominance. The partial correlation coefficients are contained in the Appendix (Tables 49—52) and are only briefly dis- cussed at this point. Generally the partials portray the same patterns as the zero-order correlation coefficients. The partials indicate that the statistical association between community social structure variables and fertility is not wholly due to the influence of metropolitan centers on their hinterlands. Even after metropolitan dominance is controlled, the first—order partials reflect for the most part a significant relationship between fertility and com— munity social structure. Some significant patterns among the partials are worth mentioning. For employment of farm- ers and farm managers only three urban coefficients among the divisions reflect a significant association with fertil- ity and these are positive. Highest coefficients are found in the rural—farm hinterland and these are mostly signifi- cant and negative in direction. The pattern for employment of farm laborers and foremen remains inconsistent. The direction of association and significance of the relation- ships remain almost unchanged also for the indices of socio— economic status as well as wife's alternative opportunities. With respect to the distribution of ever—married females in the child-bearing ages, by partialling out the effects of it 291 metropolitan dominance, the tendency for urban coefficients for both ever—married females ages 15—24 and 25-34 to exceed the rural coefficients is increased. Additional evidence of the existence of an indig- enous relationship between fertility and local community conditions, extraneous to metropolitan dominance, is ob- tained from a review of multiple-partial correlation coef— ficients controlling for distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. Table 27 arrays the multiple-partial correlation coefficients (r2) which indicate the proportion of variation in fertility explained by the combined effects of all community social structure variables after metropol- itan dominance has been partialled out. All coefficients are significantly different from zero, hence, it is assumed that fertility is a function of the local conditions of rural and urban hinterland communities apart from the dom- inance of metropolitan centers. Urban coefficients, how- ,ever, exceed both rural sectors in seven of the nine divi— sions. Tables 28 through 31 provide the multiple-partial correlation coefficients of fertility and the paired vari- ables which represent the four broad dimensions of community social structure, each coefficient controlled for the influ- ence of the metropolitan dominance variable. These tables indicate further that the combined effect of these paired variables reflecting community social structure exert a sig— nificant influence on fertility over and above metropolitan I1-IIIE Lf‘ t C C -.H Una. L L 000 L O FRO .1. Irr R. l ‘1‘ TL F¥DI.U mu m... -H 3 02:3 .0 292 .Aumucmo smuflaomouuma mo mNHm tam mocmumfipv mosmcHEOU Cmuflaomouumz ax .OHumn muflafluumm m>aumassso.w . #CQHUHWMQOU GOHHMHMHHOU amauummlmamfluass tam coflumsflfiumump mHQHuHSE mo ucmflowmmmoo cmmzumn mocmummmwmaa .Hm>ma mo. mzu um oumN Eoum ucmHmMMHU kHUGMUHMHQmHme omo. vow. wam. omo. tomm. *QOM. mac. towm. *mwm. ooo. amwm. amwm. moo. ahmm. xmmm. mmo. awha. *Nom. owe. them. *mmm. Nvo. *mam. «00m. Nfia. ammo. tomm. mma. aoam. *mmfl. NNO. awwa. «mod. mmo. mmm. mmd. who. tflmv. *mnm. moo. *Hmm. *fimw. moo. *Hofi. *mmfi. H00. Rmmm. swam. omo. ammm. amom. NNO. amoa. *HmH. Nmo. *oom. *NmN. NmN. *HMH. tmwm. bmm. teem. *Hmn. hmo. *mam. *th. H.im..mva 4*m m m Enablamudm H. azswa *«Q N N Enmwsozlamusm ll moo. .moe. ewe. msam> mmmum>< mmo. amem. ammo. ogweomm meo. ammm. *eem. cemucsoz mmo. «map. , *ooo. Hmuucmo nusom ummz aoo. *ovm. aawm. Hmuucmo nusom ummm oeo. *Hmm. «mam. oflucmaua nusom ovo. *Hmm. *Hmw. Hmuucmo :uuoz ummz mmo. ammm. toae. Hmuucmo npuoz ummm baa. «mmm. :mem. oeucmHum mavens Neg. *smm. tome. pcmamcm 3mz Hmo. anom.. «wmm. mmeasm omeHzp Ram H Am NVNH m mcoflmfl>flm 0cm m m mmumum capes: chHD wDOCHEHmuaoo coma "mocmpflmmu an .mcowmw>flp tam mmumum pmuflcb msocflsumucoo How musmsHEOU cmuflaomouuma How wGHHHOHpGOU musuosnum HMHUOm muHcsEEoo paw muflafluumm mo ANHV mucmaoflmmmoo coaumamnuoo Hafiunmmlmamfluasa tsp Ammv coaumsflfiumumo mamfluHSE mo usmflowmmmou mo comanmmaoo .hm magma .t -... r.. J a: c .34- 1 .fi a s 3 p: I A“ “H 3 I- \ 4r; ah .p 7.» m. Hr“ 0;..qu a» C U -.H U ..H ...» pH .3 C U MN. at C «U ...H M .... ls :nv T... H. (4 .I I‘ll urn .- mm. :4. -40 U. ..w. .. :CP. Luv INN C. x «~53? 293 .Aumucmo smuflaomouums mo mNHm tcm mocmumfltv mocmsHEOG cmuflaomouumz ax .OHpmu muflaflpumm m>wuma5§do M .pdmwowmmmou coaumamuuou HMfluHmmlmHmfluada tam coflumsafiumump mHmHuHSE mo ucmHOmemoo cmmBqu mo:mnmwma0**% MNH.M Nmaa .Hm>ma mo. opp um oumn Eoum quHmMMHp MaucmoHMHcmHme 000. who. mmH. mHH. HHH. mNN. boo. moo. Nma. msam> mmmnm>¢ ano. *Hoo. «Nma. Hma. «oma. *nmN. mma. «oma. *mOM. oawaomm mNo. thoo. tome. mNH. ammo. emom. hmo. ammo. aowa. camucsoz ooo. *Nmo. *Nmo. Hao. «owN. *th. Nmo. team. twee. Hmuucmo nudom pmmB Noo. *QHH. *mHH. Hoo. ammo. *mmo. Hoo. *Omo. tame. Hmuucmu nusom ummm mmo. ammo. ammo. mwo. awwo. ammo. boo. ammo. awoa. UHpsmau¢ nusom omo. ammo. *Nmo. hmo. ooo. «nNo. moo. moo. ammo. Hmuucmo nuuoz ummz emo. *OHH. xfloa. moo. admo. *NMH. omo. emao. *Nmo. Hmuusmo nuuoz ummm mva. twee. *Nma. owm. Mao. Room. mma. Hoo. amma. oaucmau< matte: mha. «Nwa. eham. 0mm. *Nmm. amvo. mom. aaea. «mem. tamamcm 3oz mNo. aeao. ammo. moo. ammo. *hNH. oeo. anoa. ahea. mme¢em QMBHZD team H.AMNVMH m seam H.Ava%H m Reta H.5mmvwn m chHmH>HQ tam N **N N ¥¥N N %*N mmumum UmuHCD Eummlamusm Emmmcozlamusm chHD msosflsumcoo owma "mocmpflmmu >9 .mQOHmfl>fl© paw mmumum pmpflcb msocflfinwucoo mom mocmsflEOG smuflaomouumfi How mGHHHOHuGOU AcoflumNHstHsv chfiumm Isuuo Hmnsuasoflumm Ga ucmahonEm tam muflafluumm mo ANHV unmaoflmmmou coflumamunoo Hmwpummlmamwuasfi 6cm Ammv coflpmcHEHmumU mamfluass mo usmflofiwmmoo mo cemwummEou .mN mHQmB r .. . .r _, witLCL LC AIL \ .:.~U.H.HVJ.HL..u CCU :Qfiu m..~.U.u-..~CU 1 w r. .r -.. FIFE CCU AJEV :QH J...:-.::Humanfiso.w .ucmfloflmwmoo sowpmamuuoo Hmfluummloamfluasa ocm coflumcflsuouoo mHmHuHDE mo ucmfloflmmwoo cmmBqu oUGmHmMMHosea mva.% Nm .Hm>ma mo. msu um OHoN Scum usmHmMMflo mauGMUHMHcoflma ¥% Hoo. oHH. oha. NHH. oma. ooN. moo. Hoa. omN. m5am> momum>< Hoo. Roma. *mfiN. moo. «mom. *omo. ova. «mON. *Nmm. Damaomm mNo. moo. *mNo. ooa. sva. towm. Noo. towN. *mam. chuQSOS ooo. amoN. amoN. oao. RONm. tomm. mmo. toom. toow. Hmuusmo Susom ummz Noo. *Noo. *«oo. Hoo. Roma. *ooa. Noo. *mmo. «ooo. Hmuucmv npsom ummm Hmo. tamo. *NHH. mmo. ahma. *moa. moo. *moa. *moa. UHquHufi Susom Nmo. *ooa. *HON. wNo. thoo. *HNH. mmo. «mNH. eawa. Hmuucmu zuHOZ umoB Hmo. «moa. aoHN. Noo. tooo. *Nma. moo. «moo. *ooa. Hmuucmo Spuoz ummm oma. ooo. *oma. ooN. Hoo. *HoN. NmH. towo. RNoH» Uflpcmaufi maooflz boa. tamo. emoN. oom. *mmN. *dmm. mmN. NNo. *th. ocmaocm 3oz vNo. ammo. *Noa. ooo. *mmo. *HmH. mvo. «ooo. *omo. mMBdBm QMBHZD aeao H.Ameku m ««*o H.Amvku m *a«o H.Ameku m muoflmg>flo ppm N atN N *tN N «%N I. mmumum panama EHmmIHMHSM EHMWQOZIHMHSM GMQHD WSOCHEHOHCOU oooH "mocooflmou an .chHmH>flo ocm moumum omuacb msocflaumucoo Mom mosmcflsoo cmpflaomouuma How ocflaaonucoo mSumum UHEOGOUoIOHUOm ocm muflaflunom mo A no usmfioflmmmoo coaumamnuoo ammuummlmamfluasa osm Ammo coflumcflfiumuoo mHmHuHDE mm acmAUHmmooo mo somflnmmaoo .oN manme A N y: 231w U CZH EMU...“ O? y P ... Turf» t5. OHQHuHSE ’N(‘\ ..‘fhriurcor.l“f.\([ LO uCQfl UHLL ECU LO alof~ F i$ «H h f\.-h lbf\p(\ C0 WHH CQECU on. NJHIQLMFNw 295 .Aumucoo smuflaomonuma mo mNHm ocm oosmumflov oucmcflfioo swpflaomouumz ax .oHumH mpaaflunom m>fiumassso % .ucmwoflmmmou coaumamunoo HMfluummlmHmfluHSE ocm coflumsflsumuoo mamfluasa mo pcmfluammmoo GmmBumn oquummmaQast boH.M N .Ho>ma mo. opp um oumn Eonm usmuommao mausmowmflcowma mat Noo. moo. mNH. mNH. ooa. omN. ooo. voa. NON. ®5Hm> momnm>¢ ooo. Hoo. ammo. me. wao. *moa. wma. *moa. «NOm. UHMflUmm «No. «moo. *Nho. baa. *mma. tooN. moo. amHN. amoN. Gwmucfioz Hoo. ammo. avmo. wao. *Nvo. aomo. Noo. aomo. amma. Hmnpcmu flusom ummB Noo. awoa. *ooa. ooo. abom. abom. Hoo. *VHH. *mHH. Hmnucmo nusom ummm Hmo. *Hmo. *Nmo. mmo. aboa. *mON. woo. ammo. *NmH. UHpcmau< nusom mmo. tomo. *omo. mNo. «wao. saoo. hmo. tmNH. *mma. Hmuusmo QUHOZ ummB omo. *hNo. aomo. moo. *omo. thmH. who. aawo. *oHH. Hmuucmo SuHOZ ummm Nma. mNo. amha. moN. ammo. *mmm. hmH. «NmH. *ooN. UHquau< GHUUHE owH. aoHH. *ooN. oom. amma. aon. ooN. boo. tth. pcmamcm 302 mNo. «mNo. *omo. boo. ammo. *mva. Noo. tomo. tooo. mMBHQ Uflm N **N N «*N N aaN mmpmum pangs: Eummlamusm EHMmCOZIHmmsm swamp mSOCHEHmuaOO oooH "mosmoflmon an .mQOHmH>Ho ocm mmumum omufisb wsosflauwusoo Mom mocmsflEoo cmuflaomouumfi Mow oceaaonusoo mofluflasuuommo m>wumcumuam m.oma3 ocm wuflafluumm mo ANHV usmfloflmwmoo cowumawnuoo Hafiuummlmamfluasfi ocm Ammo Goaumsflsnouoo mamauasfi mo ucmwoflmmmoo mo comHummEoo .om manme ... l ... ...» k (C re L. C CO H. A. .... ONZZUU . H. Mn 0 N. «N H. ..N H .Anmpcmo Cmuflaomouums mo mNHm ocm mosmumflov oUCMGHEoo cmuflaomouuoz X .oflpmu suflaguumm m>npmassao » 296 .usmfloflmmmou COHumaoHHoo Hafiuummlmamfluasfi ocm coaumcafiuouoo mamfluHSE mo ucmfloflmmooo cmmemQ mocmummmwmaa« omH MM*¥ N .Ho>oH mo. may no onmn Eoum uconoMMHo NHuCMUNMHcoflmt moo. omo. moa. Hma. Hmo. Noa. ooo. hma. mmN. osHm> momum>¢ Nho. tooo. *oHH. wma. mHo. aboa. mma. *Hma. tomm. oamaomm NNo. tome. *Nma. omH. omo. *oma. Noo. ahma. *oHN. Camussoz ooo.. ooo. ooo. oao. aomo. evmo. mno. Roma. *NmN. Hmuucmo nudom umoB Noo. Hoo. moo. Hoo. *hHo. «mac. Hoo. anom. emom. Hmuucmo Susom ummm mmo. *Nao. amoo. woo. tomo. emoo. ooo. amva. *Nom. newsmaud susom omo. ammo. *ooo. mNo. «boo. *Noo. moo. «ooN. *on. Hmuusoo Quuoz “mm: omo. eono. *Hma. moo. *omo. avma. omo. *mwN. «mom. Hmuusmu sunoz ummm mma. ooo. Roma. mom. omo. anom. ova. ammo. *oom. oausmaum oaooflz moa. Hmo. teem. Hmw. eoho. «oom. mmN. oNo. *NoN. ocmaocm 3oz mNo. ammo. amvo. omo. «0mo. aooa. mmo. amoa. tome. mmemam QMBHZD *RtQ H.Aowv%H Nm ¥¥%Q H.Aomv%H m *ttm H.AomVNH Nm mGOHmfl>HQ GEM m ...... l m 3m! m .3. mmumum ©3ch Eummlamnsm EummCOZIHmHsm chHD msosHEHmucoo oooa "oocmowmmu an .mQOHmH>flo ocm mmumum omuwcb msosflfinmpcoo How musmcflfioo chHHomouumE How ocwa IHouucoo musuosuum mom oanmmuooamo ocm muwafluumm mo ANHV ucmHUHmmmoo QOHuMHmHHoo HmfiuummlmamfluHSE ocm Ammo coflumsflaumumo mHmHuHDE mo ucoflowmmmoo mo comflumgeou .Hm magma (U rh the (De: C011 Rura \ 297 dominance. Employment in agricultural occupations is statis- tically significant, especially in the rural-farm hinter- lands. Higher coefficients are found in the rural sectors than the urban except for the West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific divisions. Socio-economic status is also sig— nificant in most cases with rural coefficients exceeding the urban with exception of the Middle Atlantic, West South Central, and Mountain divisions. Wife's alternative oppor- tunities and demographic age structure coefficients are clearly higher in the urban hinterland than the rural. Coefficients are significant in most cases except for the demographic age structure variables in rural—farm areas which tend toward being nonsignificant. These data suggest the support of the hypothesis that fertility is also a function of the conditions of the local community as well as metropol— itan dominance. This finding raises some doubt, then, as to the pervasive influence of metropolitan centers as organizing agents of characteristics of hinterland communities. This finding lends support to the ideas expressed in the articles by Grigg and by Anderson and Collier.l In other words, if metropolitan dominance was the primary determinant of inter- community variation in urban and rural hinterlands, one would 1Charles M. Grigg, "A Proposed Model for Measuring the Ecological Process of Dominance," Social Forces, XXXVI (December, 1957), 128—31; and Theodore R. Anderson and Jane Collier, "Metropolitan Dominance and the Rural Hinterland," Rural Sociology, XXI (June, 1956), 157. 298 expect that coefficients, controlling for metropolitan dominance, would prove to be nonsignificant. This is not the case with respect to the influence of internal community characteristics on fertility behavior. Hypothesis 4 Community fertility behavior is more a function of dis— tance and size of a dominating metropolitan center in the urban hinterland, but more a function of local com- munity social structure in the rural hinterland, when distance and size of the dominating metropolitan center are controlled. We have established that community social structure is partially determined by metropolitan dominance and that community fertility behavior is a function of both metropol- itan dominance and the indigenous characteristics of local hinterland communities. The question which is raised by this fourth hypothesis is whether fertility levels of urban communities is more a function of metropolitan dominance than the fertility of rural communities? This hypothesis is based on the fact that urban hinterland communities tend to concen- trate in closer proximity to metropolitan centers than rural hinterland communities. It is assumed that as distance in- creases from metropolitan centers, the ordering influence of metropolitan centers diminishes and the influence of local community conditions increases. To test this hypothesis two types of statistics will be employed: (1) multiple-partial correlation coefficients of fertility and community social structure controlling for 299 metropolitan dominance and (2) the standard partial regres- sion coefficients (beta coefficients) of each of the inde- pendent variables estimated from the multiple regression equations. The multiple-partials will indicate the amount of variation in fertility explained by community social structure over and above metropolitan dominance. The beta coefficients, on the other hand, will reflect the relative importance of each of the independent variables in account- ing for fertility variation, holding constant the effects of all other independent variables. With respect to the multi— ple—partials, the combined effects of more than one variable on fertility is considered, holding constant only one vari— able, viz., metropolitan dominance. On the other hand, with respect to the beta coefficients, only the effect of one independent variable is estimated, holding constant several other variables, including metropolitan dominance as well as other community social structure variables. By ranking the beta coefficients in each regression equation in terms of their relative size, we can come to some conclusion as to which single variables are relatively more important in determining fertility levels. In comparing these rankings for urban and rural areas, we would expect to find metropol- itan dominance as one of the most important determinants of urban fertility, but for rural fertility we would expect that some or all of the single variables reflecting community social structure would be more important than metropolitan 300 dominance. With respect to the multiple-partial correlation coefficients, our expectation is that controlling for metro— politan dominance will reduce the correlation of fertility and community structure to such an extent in urban areas that coefficients in the rural areas would be considerably larger. Obviously because of the fact that two different types of statistics are employed to test the same hypothesis, it might occur that the results of the two analyses will not be the same. Although both types of statistics actually test the hypothesis, it is assumed that the analyses of beta coefficients will be the better test because of the fact that more variables are being controlled. In the multiple- partial analysis only the effect of metropolitan dominance on fertility is controlled for each coefficient. Further- more, we can already at this point expect some difficulty in supporting this hypothesis because of the fact that on the basis of the preceding analyses wife's alternative opportunities and demographic age structure were found to have coefficients larger in urban areas than rural, even when metropolitan dominance was controlled. For this reason, the beta coefficients are expected to be the better test of the hypothesis. First, then, let us consider the multiple—partial correlation coefficients of community social structure and fertility. Does the elimination of the effects of metropol- itan dominance reduce urban coefficients to levels below rural coefficients? Table 27 provides the multiple-partial DOHfarm partiall VariableS me“013011" 301 coefficients of fertility and community social structure variables combined, controlling for metropolitan dominance. In all divisions but two, New England and East South Central, the urban coefficient exceeds the rural. The average value of the multiple-partials for urban areas is .409, for rural— nonfarm .335 and rural-farm .264. The hypothesis is not supported by these data. This same table, however, provides a comparison of the multiple-partial and the coefficient of multiple determination for each division and residential sector. The difference between these two coefficients indi— cates the proportion of explained variation of fertility which is lost when metropolitan dominance is partialled out. For most of the divisions this value (the difference between the coefficient of multiple determination and the multiple- partial) is higher in the urban areas than the rural-farm, but in the case of four divisions rural-nonfarm exceeds the urban, and these are in three highly metropolitanized divi- sions (New England, Middle Atlantic, and East North Central) and the Mountain division. Actually, on the basis of aver- age size of the difference between the coefficients of mul— tiple determination and the multiple-partials, the rural- nonfarm sector shows the greatest amount of loss doe to the partialling of metropolitan dominance. Tables 28 through 31 compare the multiple-partial correlation coefficients involving fertility and paired variables of community social structure, controlling for metropolitan dominance, and the coefficients of multiple (D 302 determination for the three variables on fertility. For the variables measuring employment in agricultural occupations (Table 28) the multiple-partial correlations tend to be greater for rural areas, with the exception of West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific divisions. The average value of the multiple-partial coefficients is largest for rural- nonfarm sectors, but lowest for rural-farm. Although the urban difference between the multiple—partial and the coef— ficient of multiple determination is almost always greater than the rural-farm difference, and sometimes greater than the rural-nonfarm, the proportion lost in urban areas due to the partialling of metropolitan dominance is not enough to reduce the multiple-partial coefficients clearly below the level of rural-farm and rural—nonfarm coefficients. It should be noted, however, that whereas for the coefficients of multiple determination four of the divisions revealed urban coefficients higher than either rural coefficients, for the multiple-partial only two urban coefficients exceed either rural sectors. Hence, for employment in agricultural occupations the hypothesis is partially supported. Socio-economic status (Table 29) similarly indicates more frequently higher multiple-partial coefficients in either rural-nonfarm or rural-farm areas. But again, the highest average value is found in the rural—nonfarm areas and the lowest the rural-farm rather than urban. But this pattern is also true for the coefficients of multiple deter— mination where metropolitan dominance is allowed to influence (‘1' CO wi Cie Pol. Cie: 303 fertility. In fact, for the total correlation the urban coefficient is larger than either rural coefficient only for West South Central. For the multiple-partials three divi- sions are found to have urban coefficients exceeding either rural coefficient (Middle Atlantic, West South Central and Mountain). In the case of the urban sector of four divi— sions, in comparing the multiple—partial and coefficient of multiple determination, a greater proportion of fertility variation explained is lost by partialling out metropolitan dominance, but it is not enough to reduce the urban multiple— partials below the rural. Hence the hypothesis is only par- tially supported by the socio—economic status dimension of community social structure. Table 30 compares the multiple-partial correlation coefficients and coefficients of multiple determination for wife's alternative opportunities. With respect to the latter coefficient four of the divisions have urban coeffi- cients larger than the rural sectors, but partialling metro— politan dominance seems to affect the rural—nonfarm coeffi- cients more than the urban. With respect to the multiple— partials six of the divisions have urban coefficients larger than the rural. The average value of the multiple—partial is still highest for rural-nonfarm and lowest for rural—farm rather than urban. While rural—farm coefficients lose rela- tively little (6 percent) of the variation in fertility explained by controlling metropolitan dominance, the urban coefficients are not significantly reduced from the level of 304 coefficients of multiple determination to bring them below rural-farm levels. The hypothesis is not supported in the case of wife's alternative opportunities. With respect to demographic age structure of women of childbearing age (Table 31), the coefficients of multiple determination are much too high and the effects of metropol- itan dominance too little to alter the basic pattern of highest coefficients in the urban hinterlands of the divi— sions. Eight divisions indicate urban coefficients of multiple determination exceeding either rural coefficients and, when metropolitan dominance is partialled, nine divi- sions have urban coefficients higher than the rural. The hypothesis is not supported by demographic age structure. Of the four broad categories of community social structure, only employment in agricultural occupations and socio— economic status tend to indicate some support of the hypoth— esis. In fact the evidence seems to suggest that the rural- nonfarm hinterland is more affected by the partialling of metropolitan dominance than the urban since for all four categories of community social structure the greatest pro— portions of explained fertility variation are lost in this sector. A more sensitive test of the relative importance of metropolitan dominance and community social structure in each of the residential types of hinterlands, however, is provided by the beta coefficients. The relative size of the beta coefficients compared with the size of the beta (I) 83C 0111' 305 coefficients for all other independent variables employed in the same multiple regression equation is indicative of the relative importance of that particular independent variable in accounting for variation in the dependent variable, fertility. According to the hypothesis, then, we should expect to find a tendency for metropolitan dominance to be ranked first in determining fertility levels for urban hinterland communities, whereas the community social struc- ture variables should tend to be ranked above metropolitan dominance for rural hinterland communities. Let us consider the rankings of beta coefficients for each division, comparing the urban and rural patterns. In this manner we use the results for each division as a test case of the hypothesis. After considering each divi- sion separately we shall attempt to summarize the patterns among the divisions with the use of average rank values for each independent variable. Tables 32 through 40 contain the beta coefficients and rankings by residential hinterland for each division. According to Table 32 New England is a poor fit of our expectations. Though metropolitan dominance is rela- tively more important in urban than rural-farm areas, none of the coefficients are statistically significant for the three residential sectors. For urban and rural-nonfarm com- munities in New England four social structure variables are more important than metropolitan dominance and in rural-farm areas seven social structure variables exceed metropolitan LITvMHUHHLHML r fhh. NV MW 306 .GOHumsom coflmmouoou mHmHuHsE “masofluumm CH ooosaosfl mmHQmHHm> ucmocmmmoCH Hmnuo Ham nufl3 ooummeou Muflafluumm ca ocflussooom CM mocmuHomEH m>flumamu >9 manmwnm> unmocmmmosfl mo xcmmat COHuMHHm> Mom .Hm>ma mo. ozu um OHmN Eonm usmuommao mausmoflwflcoflma o nma.: m omo.: o ooo.: Amxo emumm mom mmamsmm m mmH.n k eeo.u a *oom.u imxv wanna mom mmHmEmm musuosuum 0mm oanmmuoosmn m mom. a ems. m aoo.u Akxv pcmENOHQEm mamsmm H *koa.u m ammm.u n meo.u onv msoocH panama mofluficsuuommo m>flumsuouam m.mMH3 N *Nmm.n H ammv.u m amev.u Amxv msooaH seesaw a mac. o mmo.u m Hmo. Aexv coflumospm msumum UHEOQOUMIONUOm v omm. m Room. a *onm. Amxv cmsmuom cam mumuonmq Enmm h nNH. o omo. m omo.: ANXV mumomcmz Eumm ocm mumaumm macaummdooo amusuasofluod QH usofimmmem o Nmo.l m oma.l m wNN.| Aaxv mocmcflsoo cmuflaomonuoz tam hm aam mm **m mm manmflum> pcmocommocH EHMhIHMHSm EHMHQOZIHMHUZ SMQHD ocmaocm 3oz oooH "mosmoamou an .GONmfl>Ho ocmaocm 3oz Mom muflafluumm Ga sofluMHHm> How ocflucsooom SH mommuuomsfl m>aumamu >9 oHQmHHm> unmocmmooaw mo xcmu osm Ammo ucmfloflmmmoo mumm .Nm magma 307 dominance in accounting for fertility variation. Family income and farm laborers and foremen are consistently more important than metropolitan dominance in all three residen- tial hinterland communities. Metropolitan dominance in New England appears to have relatively little influence in determining fertility levels. New England, then, does not support the hypothesis. The beta coefficients and rankings for Middle Atlantic division are given in Table 33. In contrast with New England, for Middle Atlantic metropolitan dominance is extremely important in determining fertility levels. In all residential sectors metropolitan dominance ranks first. How— ever, this pattern does not support our hypothesis either, since there are no community social structure variables in the rural areas which are more important than metropolitan dominance. Table 34 presents the results for East North Central division. Metropolitan dominance is again significant in accounting for fertility variation and in all three residen— tial sectors, although it is ranked first in rural-nonfarm, second urban, and third rural—farm. The hypothesis, then, is partially supported in the contrast of urban and rural— farm areas, but not in the comparison of urban and rural- nonfarm. In rural-farm areas two social structure variables are more important than metropolitan dominance: education and employment of farmers and farm managers. For urban OCOH «OUCUUHWQH >3 .COHNH>NU UHUCGHJ< UACUNZ MOM XQHNNUHUH :fi CONUUHHJ> MOM WZflOCZOUUQ :4 TUCUHHCQEH U>HU5HUL k2 UHQCfiH3> UCEUCUQUTCfl LO MCCM 3:5 «.my JCUflUflLLUCU SOUS -Mfi QNQZB 308 .GOHumsoo conmmHomH oHQHuHDE HMHdoHuumm CH omosHUGH mmHQMHHm> ucmoaommocH Hmnuo HHm nuHB oonmmeoo huHHHuHmm cH soHumHHm> How ocHucsooom CH mocmunomEH o>HHMHmH >9 oHQMHHm> usmonmmwocH mo mem*« .Hm>oH mo. on“ um oumN Eoum ucmHmMMHo hHuchHMHGonR o oMH.I m MNo.I m #50. onv fimlmN mom mOHmem s ¢MH.I n mNo.: a ammH.u lmxo emumH mom mmHmemm mucuosnpm mom UHnmmuooEmQ m moH. N «moN.| o ooo. Ahxv usmENOHQEm meEom m mvN.I m mNo.: m *ooq.u ioxv msoocH mHmsmm mmHuHcsunommo o>HumchuH< m_mMH3 m Noo.- m mao.u m ammm.: Amxo msoocH HHHamm m who.: a omo. m oHo. Hexv coHumospm msumum UHEOQOUMIOHUOm m *Hmm. m aon. H mNo.- meo cafimuom ppm mumuoan sump v th.I o m¢o.1 o mHo. ANxv muoomsmz Eumm ocm mHmEHmm mcoHpmmduoO HMHSHHSUHHo¢ CH ucmENONmEm H *Hee.- H «aHm.n H *mka.u HHxV mocmcHsop ampHHoQOHums n d m **m .m aem .m **m .m oHQMHum> ucoocommocH Enmmleusm EummsozIHmusm swamp UHuCMHu¢ mHUUHS oooH uousmonmu an .GOHmH>Ho UHucmem mHoon Mom NHHHHHHQM :H coHumHum> How osHussooom :H mocmuuomEH o>HHMHmH >9 mHQMHHm> ucoocomoosH mo xcmu ocm A.mv usmHonmmoo muom .mm mHQmB l..\ .\ r\ F ‘ r\ r\ '1‘ l u! F.l\ fi "U1 kwtv'H - . . - . r H 1 l l i C C i . LEE . U ...E MC H. > a H H H HAUL. C H 20H. U OH HZ> (HO 3H . . - . . - . .. -. : .HH.EZOU u OUCGHHOQEH C>H UGHOH >3 m. L . ... Uh CH UHQSHHwa ..HCOUCUQOTCH LO VEHHQH 3C3 «.m: HZOHUHLHOOU H.033 .vm aNQmS 309 .COHumCom COHmmmComC mHmHuHCE CMHCUHuHmm CH omoCHoCH moHQMHHm> quoCmmooCH Hono HHm CuHB omummfioo NHHHHpHmm CH COHHMHCm> Com oCHuCCOUUm CH wUCMHHomEH m>HHMHmC >9 oHQMHCm> quoCmmwoCH mo MCmmtt .Hm>mH mo. mCu um 0Com Eoum HConMMHo mHquUHMHCone onv omlmN mom mmHmEmm m emo. m moo. H mac. a *mmm.n o HemH.u H HOHe.u meo emumH mom mmHmEmm musuosuum mom UHCMMHmOEoQ m emoN. h who. m omo. Anxv quENOHmEm mHmEom H .moH.u a .HmH.u a .mmH.u ioxv meoocH mHmEmm moHuHCCuHQmQO o>HCMCHmuH< m.omH3 m omo.: m aomm.n m *oom. lmxv psoocH sHHsmm H *on.u m *mHH.u m *NoH. Hexv commmuspm msumum UHEOCOUmIOHUom o HemH. m moo. o mmo.u mev swamuom ppm mumuopmH sump N «omN.I N *me.I o omo.! ANXV mumoMsz 8Com oCm mumfiumm mCOHummCooO HmCCuHCUHCo¢ CH quENMHmEm m emmm.n H ammm.u m amom.u HHxv mocmcHsop cmpHHooouumz m n H *«m .m tam .m tam .m mHQmHCm> quoCmmmoCH EHMWIHMHSNL EHMHCOZIHMHSM CGQHD. HmuuCoU Cuuoz ummm oooH "moCmonmC Np .ConH>Ho HmuuCoU Cuuoz ummm Com NCHHHuHom CH COHCMHCm> Com oCHuCCOUUm CH GUCmuHomEH m>HumHmH >9 oHQMHCm> HCooConoCH mo meu oCm A.mv quHonmmoo mumm .wm oHQMB cie: tho: rura inar exce marr sect more poli OHly ‘ 310 areas the percent of ever-married females in the ages 15-24, as a reflection of local community conditions, is more important than metropolitan dominance in accounting for fertility variation. Hence the case of East North Central division only hints at the support of the hypothesis. Table 35 compares the urban and rural beta coeffi- cients for West North Central division. In this case, though there are community social structure variables in the rural sectors which are more important than metropolitan dom- inance, metropolitan dominance in urban areas as well is exceeded by the relative importance of two variables: ever— married females ages 15-24 and female income. In both rural sectors education and ever-married females ages 15-24 are more influential in determining fertility levels than metro- politan dominance. The case of West North Central suggests only a tendency to support the hypothesis. The relative importance of the independent variables for South Atlantic are indicated in Table 36. In this case the observed pattern for the relative importance of metropol- itan dominance in affecting fertility among the residential sectors is opposite the expected. Metropolitan dominance is very important in rural-farm and rural—nonfarm areas, but relatively unimportant for urban. For urban communities the social structure variables which seem to influence fertility more than metropolitan dominance are females ages 15-24, socio—economic status, and wife's alternative opportunities. SOON "SUCOUHWQH >3 .EOHNH>HU HGHJCOU CUHOZ UHOS MOM NUHNHUHOL CH COHUGHMW> HOL UCHUCSOUUE 3H @UCWUHOAEH ®>HUQHOH AD OHQEflHfl> UCOUCUQOWCH LO XCQH DEW «.mv HCWHUHWNUOU Gumm .mm UNQQE 311 .COHumCom COHmmmComC mHmHuHCE HMHCUHuHmm CH omoCHUCH mmHQmHCm> quoCmmoUCH HoCuo HHm CHHB omummfioo NCHHHqum CH COHCMHHm> Com oCHuCCooom CH ooCmuComEH m>HumHoH >9 oHQmHHm> quoCmmooCH mo memaa .Hm>mH mo. oCu pm OHmN EOHM quCwmeo hHquUHMHCona o ooo. m ooo. H Hmo. onv omImN mow monEom m Hemm.u m aomm.n H amoe.u Amxv emumH mom mmHmEmpll mCCuoCCum mod UHCmmummEmQ o moo. H NHo. m HHMH. ino mamsHOHosm mHmEmm m *omH.| o oHo.I N eHmN.I A Xv mEOUCH mHmEmm mmHHHCCuCommo m>HHMCCouH¢ m.mMH3 H meo.u e amvH.u a aoom.u Amxv msoucH HHHEMC H *Hmm.u H amom.u o «omo.: Hexv C0pr056m msumum UHEOCOUMIOHoom N aeom. m omo. m mNo. Amxo cmsmuom ppm mCmHOCMH spam m mNo.I m Homo.l o oHo.I ANxv mumoMsz Eumm oCm mCmEHmm . mCOHummmUOO HCHCHHCUHCod CH quENOHmEm e *Hom.u m aeHH.: m amom.n inv mommaHCOp amuHHomouumz m .|d m **m .m *«m .m **m .m oHQMHCm> uCooCmmmoCH summlensm EHMMCOZIHmHCm CmQCD HmuquO CHCOZ ummz oooH "mUCoonoC an .ConH>Ho HmuquO Cuuoz ummz Cow NCHHHpCom CH COHCMHHm> How oCHuCCOUUm CH ooCmuuomEH m>HumHoC NC oHQMHHm> uCoUCmmmoCH mo meH oCm A.mv quHUHmmmou mpom .mm mHQmB . u L. tllluruirirrIKFKKfi PAW flirt; r.. +ircrL»: m. n....\/ —. 1v .... _. .r..~.H >A~ UH 3* ”...—m .H ”UNV “FL mUPoHL mUflwflLLF~ H. w G VHFL 5th.. MVNMWJ «hm» ULLMIUHUHHkW “WOO Wavy muMK 0 0M: UNQNVE 312 .COHumCom ConmoComH mHmHuHCE CmHCoHuumm CH omoCHoCH mmHQMHHm> “CooCommoCH HmCuo HHm CCH3 omnmmeoo muHHHuHmm CH COHCMHCm> Com oCHuCCooum CH moCmuHomEH o>HumeC an oHQmHHm> uCooCmmmoCH mo mem** .Hm>mH mo. oCu um ouon Eouw quCoHMHo NHquUHMHCona w NHo. m ooo.: H *NOH. onv omImN mom mmHmEmm H *mOH.u a .Hem.n H emmm.u Amxv «mumH mom mmHmamm mCCHUCHum mom UHflmemmEmQ o 88H.. m .mHm.- m HHOH.I AHxv wcmsHoHCEH mHmsmm o omo.: o omo.: w *me.I A xv msoomm.mHmEmm moHuHCCuCommo m>HumCCouH< m.mMH3 m .NHH. H oHo. m «ooN.: Amxv wsoocH HHHamm N amoN.I H «hmm.l N *HHm.I w.xv COHCMODUM mCumpm UHEOCoomIOHoom v .NNH. m *mHH. o oqo. Amxv :msmuom ppm mumuoan Eumm m mHN.I o moo.l m ooo. ANxv mumomsz 8Com oCm mHmEme mCOHummCuoo HmCCuHCUHCo< CH pCmsNonEm H HOHm.| m aHHm.u o «NQH.I Aon mocmcHsop cmpHHOCOCHmz n n .dl *«m .m ¥«m .m tam .m oHQmHHm> quoCommoCH Eummleusm EumeOZIHmCCm CmQCD oHucmHua nusom oooH "moCoonmH mp .COHmH>Ho OHHCMHCC Cuzco Com NuHHHuHom CH COHHMHCm> Mom oCHuCCooom CH moCmuComEH m>HHMHmC an oHQmHCm> quoCmmooCH mo meu oCm A.mv quHOHmmoOU mumm .om oHQme Educat: Howeve' data i also types in ur polit rank Table tant ; Variak foreme metro; fertn; ables E emPlOym importa, fails tc metropol 313 Education is consistently important in both rural sectors. However, again the hypothesis is not substantiated by the data for the division. Table 37 relates to the relative importance of the independent variables in accounting for fertility levels in the East South Central division. Metropolitan dominance does not rank first for rural areas, but this is the case also for urban areas. Education is in both rural hinterland types more important than metropolitan dominance. However in urban areas four social structure variables exceed metro- politan dominance in influencing fertility levels. The hypothesis is again not supported. The beta coefficients and relative importance by rank are provided for the West South Central division in Table 38. In this case metropolitan dominance is unimpor— tant in the rural sectors and superceded by social structure variables, specifically employment of farm laborers and foremen and the socio—economic status variables. However metropolitan dominance is not important in determining urban fertility levels either, since four social structure vari- ables exceed metropolitan dominance. Both education and employment of farm laborers and foremen are consistently important in all residential sectors. The hypothesis again fails to be verified. With respect to the Mountain division (Table 39) metropolitan dominance again fails to be ranked as the most \A u: ..Hmu >|H U MMMH. FHOU n. U~#AUMUA U.Ww~..nm~ “And.“ >..u.n.H..N my...*.\-.nHH..L (a? lull .l . . P 1 x . 0H o. a. .H H a H HoHoCH MO icon Coco Om: HCQHUHCMQOU ouom -.Hm. 314 .COHumsom COHmmmComH onHuHCE CMHCoHqum CH omoCHoCH moHQMHCm> quoCmmmoCH HmCuo HHm CuH3 ooummfioo NHHHHuHmm CH CoHumHCm> Com oCHuCCooUm CH moCmuComEH m>HHMHoH an oHanCm> uCooCmmooCH mo mem«* .Ho>oH mo. mCu um OHmN Eoum uCoHoMMHo mHquoHMHCone m HHo.- m emo.u H amo. Amxo amumm mom mmHmEmm a .omH.- m .mom.u H .Noa.n Amxv amumH mom mmHmsmm mHCuUCHpm 0mm UHCmmmmOEmo H *oom.l H «ooo.: N aoom.l AHXV uCoENOHmEm mHmEmm H Hmo. a ammH. o HHH. onv mEoocH mHmsmm mmHuHCCuuommO m>HHMCHmuH¢ m.mMH3 m mmo.u m .oHo.n m ave. Amxv meoocH HHHemm o *eHH.I m .mHH.I m «amH.: 1:. Aqxv cOHumospm msumum UHEOCOUMIOHoom m .mom. o .OHH. a .HmH.n Amxo cmsmnom 6cm mumuoan EHmm N *mNm.I H HomH.I o mHo.I ANXV mumoMsz Eumm oCm mHoECmm mCoHumoCuoo HMCCHHCUHHoC CH uCoENmflmEm m .oHH.u m .OHN.I m .mHH.u AHxv mommcHEOp cmpHHoooupmz .N n 1H, *«m .m eam .m Ham .m oHQmHCm> uCooComooCH Enmmleusm ECMMCOZIHMCCm CmCHD HmuuCoO Cusom ummm oooH "moCmonoC an .COHmH>Ho HmuuCoO Cusom ummm Com NCHHHuCom CH COHumHCm> How oCHuCCouum CH ooCmuHOQEH o>HCMHmH an oHQMHCm> quoCommoCH mo meC oCm A.mv uCoHUHmwooo mumm .mm oHQmB V —q fin“ J1“! HUI". J AN) v \J .I v .. nwlwflfl.V’.V ml w.vM~ .QMII .LF LFL .. 5.- .Plh . o n .r I.‘ '1‘ o . . V t .. u IVNH A MN ~ I . "IL: M I . a - MO ,, I OH . ... m“ a . a! w ~nV~ v— uv .v I .II ..UlH « fit ‘ H An. CHhE- o: ...H . GHQQS 315 .GOHumsvm scammmnmmu mHQHuHSE Haasoflpumm CH wmwsaocfl mmaflmauw> pcmwcmmmwcfl HmSpo Ham QMAB Umummaou muHHHunm CH QOHUMHHm> How mcfluasooom SH mucmuuogefl m>aumamu an magmaum> ucmwcmmmocw mo xamm«* .Hm>ma mo. mnu um OHwN Eoum ucmHmMMHU mauchHmwnmflm¥ m mmo.u w *oaa. m *qwm. Amxv «mumm mmm mmamamm n omo.: m Imoa.u w IB¢H.I Amxv wmnma mmm mmamamm mnsuusnum mmm Uflcmmmmoamo m mmo.u m Immo.u m omo.: Anxv wcmemoamam mHmEmm o m¢o.: m mmo.n o Imoa.u A xv mEoocH mHmEmm mmfluflcsuuommo m>HpmcwmuH¢ m.mmwz N *Hmm.n m Imma.l m Imoo.u Amxv waoocH maflamm H Imo¢.: m Imam.n m *Hom.n hixv coflumosom mSuMpm UHEOQOUMIOHUom m Imam. H *wmv. H *omm. Amxv swamgom mam mumuonmq summ fl *oma.l o «moa.l n *ooo.l Amxv mummmamz Enmm cam mHmEHmm mQOHummdooO HmHSuHSUHHmm Cw ucmENOfimam m *vma.u n Inmo.u m ¥¢¢H.I Aaxv mocmcHEOG cmuflaomouumz n HI. ml ¥*m .m **m .m **m .m manmflum> ucmwcmmmmcH Eummlamnsm Eummcozlamusm GmQHD Hmuucmo nusom ummz coma "mocmwflmmu an .qoamfl>H© Hmuucmo susom ummz How wuflafluumm CH COHuMHHm> How mcflucsouom GM mocmuuomafl m>wumamu an mHQMflum> ucmwcmmmwcfl mo xcmu 6am A.mv ucmfloflmmmoo muwm .mm manme 5 I . I.I.‘I.IIIIIIVI.\III ril- L ‘ OUCGQHUQEH O>HJSHGH \AQ @HCG..~H$> UCOUCOLUCGH Mmu MESH C:m..~nm3 UCBHUWMQQOU SHOE .mm, mwfinxi~ 316 .COHumsvm COHmmmummH mHmHuHCE HMHCoHunmm CH UmUCHoCH mmHQMHHm> quowmmUCH HmCuo Ham CuHB wmummfiou MuHHHuHmm CH CoHumHnm> How mCHuCCooum CH mUCmuHOQEH m>Hanmu an mHQMHHm> quflCmmmUCH mo mem** .Hm>mH mo. mCu um OHmN EOHM quHmMMHw mHquoHMHCmHm* m moo.u m Noo.: m HHo. Amxv «mumm mom mmamamm H *va.I o *oma.u m *mom.u A xv wmnma mmm mmamamm musuosnum 0mm UHCmmummEmm m «mH.u m «OHN.I ¢ H¢H.I AHxv wamaaonam mamamm m moa.| m moo. o mmH.I A xv maooCH mHmEmm mmHuHCCpHommo m>HumCHmpH< m.mMH3 w *Nma. v *Hma.u H *Hoa. Amxv wfioocH HHHEmm H mHo. a *mom.u H *mmm.u A xv coHumosom mSHMu. m UHEOCOUMIOH 00m m mmo.n H moo.u m oao. Amxv swamuom cam mumuonmq Eumm N *mHN.I m *mmH. m *Hmm. Amxv mummMsz Eumm UCm mumaumm mCOHummCUUO HmnsuHCOHHm¢ CH quENOdem o ¢OH.I N *mmm.l m HomH.I Aaxv mocmcHaoc cmgHHomouumz WI m **m .m **m .m **m hm mHQMHum> quUCmmmUCH EHmhIHMHSm EHMWGOZIHMHSM CMQHD CHmuCCOZ oomH umUCmUHmmH >9 ~COHmH>H© CHmuCCOE How muHHHuumm CH COHHMHHm> How mCHpCCOUUm CH moCMCHOQEH m>HumHmH an mHQMHHm> quowmmUCH mo meu UCm A.mv quHUHmmmoo mumm .mm magma impor It is socia relat DORLE 317 important variable in determining urban fertility levels. It is surpassed by four other variables reflecting community social structure. While metropolitan dominance is also relatively unimportant in rural-farm areas, for the rural— nonfarm communities it ranks second. The Pacific division (Table 40) is the only case among the divisions which indicates that metropolitan dom- inance is relatively more important in determining fertility levels in urban areas than rural—farm or rural-nonfarm. But even in this case there are community social structure vari- ables which surpass metropolitan dominance in relative impor- tance. In urban areas of the Pacific division metropolitan dominance is overshadowed by education and female income and in both rural sectors, education, family income and ever- married females ages 15—24 are more important predictors of fertility than metropolitan dominance. Though this suggests the support of the hypothesis, again it does not follow exactly the expected pattern. Overall it appears that where the hypothesis fails is too great an expectation for metropolitan dominance as a relatively important variable in determining urban fertility levels compared with community social structure variables. In several divisions metropolitan dominance ranks below several community social structure variables for both rural sectors, but generally in these same cases metropolitan dom— inance did not prove to be the most important variable in 318 .COHumsvm ConmmHmmH mHmHuHCE CmHCUHuHmm CH UmUCHUCH mmHQMHHm> qupCmmmUCH Hmnuo HHm CuHB cmummEoo NCHHHuHmm CH CoHumHHm> How mCHuCCooom CH moCmuuomEH m>HHMHmH an mHQmHum> “CmoCmmmoCH mo mem«« .Hm>mH mo. msu um OHmN Eoum quHmMMHU mHquoHMHCmHm* m mwo.l m mmo. H moo. Amxv wmlmm mmm mmHmEmm m *HmN.n N .mmN.- q *HmN.u Amxv «NImH mom mmHmamm mnsuusuum 0mm UHCmmumOEmQ m NQH. o .mmH. o *meN. AHxV mamaHoHCEm mHmaom o mmo.l v *mom.l H *Hmw.l A xv mEOUCH meEmm mmHuHCCuHommO m>HHMCHmuH< m.mMH3 N .omN.I m *mvN.n m Noo.: Amxv maoocH HHHamm H NOHm.I H Hemm.n N .mmm.u Aaxv coHumoseMIl mspmum UHEOCOUMIOHoom H omo. H mmH. m Noo.: Amxv swamuom mam mumuonmg sums m H¢Q.I m mNo.I m *Hmm. Amxv mummMszlEumm UCm mHmEHmm mCoHummdooO HmHCuHSUHHm< CH pCQflNOHmEm d mmH.I m H¢ON.I m *me.l AHXV mUCMCHEO© CmuHHomonumz n n .d **m .m **m .m xxm .m mHQMHHm> qupCmmmpCH Enmmleusm EHMMCOZIHmHCm CmQCD oHHHomm ommH "mUCmUHmmH m9 .COHmH>H© UHwHomm How auHHHuumm CH COHHMHHm> How mCHuCCOUUm CH moCmuHomEH m>HHMHmH an mHQMHHm> qupCmmmpCH mo meu ow A.mv quHonmmoo mumm .om mHQma 319 accounting for urban fertility. Where metropolitan domi- nance proved to be an important variable in urban areas, it was also important in the rural sectors. Although there were tendencies among the divisions to support the hypoth— esis, generally the hypothesis failed to be substantiated. Another way of looking at the pattern of rank order of the independent variables in determining fertility levels within urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm areas, however, is to consider the average rank received by each independent variable among all the divisions. It is difficult to sum- marize the patterns which are found among the divisions when considered individually, and the use of average rank value provides at least a summary measure by which we may consider the comparison of relative importance of metropolitan domi— nance and community social structure together. Table 41 pro— vides the average rank values of each independent variable among the divisions. While these data indicate that on the average metropolitan dominance is a relatively important variable in determining fertility levels, this is true for all three residential hinterland types. On the average met- ropolitan dominance is more important in rural-nonfarm areas than urban and more important in urban areas than rural-farm. However, as the table indicates, in no residential sector is metropolitan dominance on the average ranked first among the independent variables. In urban areas ever-married females ages 15-24 exceeds metropolitan dominance in average rank value and in both rural sectors education exceeds it. Table 41 320 Table 41. Average rank among divisions of relative impor— tance of independent variables in accounting for variation in fertility measured by beta coeffi- cients, by residence: 1960 Average Rank of Beta Coefficients Rural- Rural- Independent Variable Urban Nonfarm Farm Metropolitan dominance (X1) 3.9 3.2 4.1 Employment in Agricultural Occup. Farmers and Farm Managers (X2) 6.9 6.3 4.4 Farm Laborers and Foremen (X3) 5.9 5.3 4.3 Socio-Economic Status Education (X4) 4.1 2.9 4.0 Family Income (X5) 5.2 4.2 5.2 Wife's Alternative Qpportunities Female Income (X ) 4.2 6.0 5.4 Female Employmené (X7) 6.0 4.4 4.8 Demographic Age Structure Females age 15-24 (X8) 2.4 4.7 4.6 ,Females age 25-34 (X9) 6.3 7.9 8.1 partial we must tiated. rural a: ables aI determir Suggest: in rura: These 6; as a pe: all him hinterl Communi hinterl each t3 ior, tk StrUCtt 321 On the basis of the data provided by the multiple— partial correlation coefficients and the beta coefficients we must conclude that the fourth hypothesis is not substan- tiated. with both types of statistics it was shown that in rural 22$ urban hinterlands community social structure vari- ables are more important than metropolitan dominance in determining fertility levels. These data also concur in suggesting that metropolitan dominance is most influential in rural—nonfarm hinterland communities and not urban. These data further cast some doubt on metropolitan dominance as a pervasive influence and organizing process throughout all hinterland areas vis—a-vis the influence that local hinterland communities themselves exert in determining inter— community spatial variation. In contrasting urban and rural hinterland communities, however, in terms of the impact that each type of hinterland community exerts on fertility behav- ior, these data seem to suggest that of the community social structure variables which are found to influence community fertility behavior, employment in agricultural occupations and socio—economic status are more important in rural areas whereas wife's alternative opportunities and demographic age structure are more influential in urban hinterland areas. exi not t1 5 .1‘ 1" 322 fiypothesis 5 In the more metropolitan geographic divisions compared with the less metropolitan geographic divisions, the size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center is more important in accounting for variation in commu— nity social structure and fertility behavior in both urban and rural hinterland communities. This hypothesis, of course, stems from a considera- tion of the different rates of metropolitanization which exist among the various divisions. To this point we have not considered the effect that differential rates of metro- politanization may have upon the pattern of hinterland com— munity variation as well as community fertility variation. It is assumed that the nation is moving toward a situation in which metropolitan centers become the chief "organizing" influence on intercommunity variation. Those divisions, therefore, which indicate higher levels of metropolitaniza— tion may be considered prototypes of intercommunity varia— tion patterns which will eventually emerge as the dominant pattern for all geographic divisions. Upon subdividing the nine geographic divisions into two categories, i.e., those divisions which indicate metropolitanization levels above the national average and those divisions below, we should expect to find intercommunity variation patterns more clearly the result of the "organizing" effect of metropol— itan centers in the more metropolitan divisions. In the less metropolitan divisions, the effect of metropolitan centers should not be as clear. The expected pattern in the more metropolitan divisions is spelled out in the hypothesis presex fiivis exert well varia of CC hints 323 presented above. In other words, for the more metropolitan divisions size and distance of metropolitan centers should exert greater influence on community social structure as well as community fertility behavior compared with the same variable in the less metropolitan divisions. This pattern, of course, is anticipated similarly for all residential hinterland types. Tables 42 through 44 provide a test of the impor- tance of metropolitan dominance in determining community social structure variation in the more and less metropolitan divisions for urban, rural-nonfarm, and rural-farm hinter- land areas respectively. Table 42 provides the zero-order correlation squared (an estimate of the proportion of vari- ation in the dependent variable explained by the independent variable, which in this case is metropolitan dominance) between metropolitan dominance and each of the eight indi- vidual indicators of community social structure for the urban communities in each of the nine geographic divisions. The divisions are ordered according to percent of their population residing in metropolitan areas. To facilitate the difficult task of making comparisons for such data, an average value of the squared correlation coefficient for each community social structure variable is also provided for the two categories of divisions. For urban coefficients ‘we see that for five of the average values, the more metro— politan divisions exceed the less metropolitan divisions, .COHHMNHCOQHHOQOHUOE MO HO>®A %Q WQOHWH>HU MOM OMSUUSHUW HMHUOW XOHCZEEOU UGO OUCGCHEOU COHHHCQOHUUE HO A My mUHHOflUflnHMOOU COH.UGH®IH«HOU .HmumOIHCIOHON N .Nv OHQGE 324 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um oumN Scum HCmeMMHU mHquoHMHCmme woo. MHo. Hfio. Nmo. mMH. Nmo. moo. vmo. ¢.ov mSHm> mmmum>¢ moo. ooo. ammo. moo. smmo. *HVH. MHo. moo. 0.0m HmanmU fiudom ummm ooo. ooo. Noo. sumo. *NHo. *mmo. *mmo. *omH. m.m¢ HMHUCmo SCHOZ ummB .woo. «0mo. *mHH. *mNN. *omo. *oNo. «omo. *Noo. m.mv CHmpCCOE Noo. *HNo. Hoo. goo. some. ooo. eomo. *mmo. N.om UHHCmHuC Cusom woo. Noo. woo. *omo. HHo. moo. ewHo. eon. m.mm HmupCmU Cusom ummz l CmuHHommuumz mmmH emo. NmH. Hmo. Noo. mmN. moo. oHo. mvo. o.¢H mCHm> mmmnm>¢ *mNo. *mNo. vao. egNo. ooo. HHo. *mNo. *mHo. H.Ho HmHquU Cunoz ummm ovo. NOON. *mNH. ewNH. emmo. oHo. emmH. *HvH. m.0H oCMHmCm 3oz mNo. *HHH. Hmo. «Hmo. some. moo. Hoo. moo. N.mH UHMHomm *HNH. HNHN. moo. moo. *mmo. Hoo. eme. eHmo. m.Hm oHuCMHuC mHoon CmuHHomoCuwz muoz NHC .ouumz CoHummHCmuHHomouumz N N N N N N N N X mo Hm>mq an mConH>HQ oomH "CmQHC .CoHummHCmuHHomoupmfi mo Hm>mH an mConH>Ho Mom mHCuUCHpm HmHUOm huHCCEEoo oCm mUCmCHEoo CmuHHomonumfi mo ANCV mquHUHmwmoo COHHMHmHHoo CmoHOIOHmN .Nv mHQmB 325 but for three average values the pattern is reversed. On the average, then, metropolitan dominance is more important in accounting for variation in employment of farm laborers and foremen, family income, female employment and ever- married females ages 15-24 and 25-34, in the more metropol— itan divisions than in the less metropolitan divisions. For employment of farmers and farm managers, education, and female income the pattern is reversed. Average differences in coefficient size are especially large for family income and ever—married females ages 15-24. In the more metropol- itan divisions, metropolitan dominance explains on the aver- age 30 percent of family income variation and 15 percent of variation for ever-married females ages 15-24, whereas for the less metropolitan divisions the average percentages are 14 and 1 respectively. Of course, using an average value for comparison does gross over several inconsistencies in the data. In several cases the coefficients of the more metropolitan divisions fall below the highest coefficients of the less metropolitan divisions, and this especially occurs for East North Central and Pacific divisions. Fur— thermore, it should be pointed out that the difference between the average values for the two categories of divi— sions is often very slight. Nevertheless on the average metropolitan dominance appears more frequently to be more important in determining community social structure varia- tion in the more metropolitan divisions than the less netropc esis is rural-1 cated farm c. sisten' Wherea. 326 metropolitan divisions. Hence we conclude that the hypoth— esis is supported to some extent by the urban sector. The hypothesis is more consistently supported by the rural-nonfarm and rural-farm average coefficients as indi— cated in Tables 43 and 44. The average value of rural—non- farm coefficients for the more metropolitan divisions con- sistently exceeds those for the less metropolitan divisions, whereas in the case of rural-farm coefficient averages six of the eight comparisons are consistent with the hypothesis. In the case of rural—nonfarm average coefficient values, again the largest difference appears for family income and ever-married females ages 15-24. On the average metropol- itan dominance in the more metropolitan divisions explains 25 percent of the variation in family income and 20 percent of the variation in ever—married females ages 15-24. In the less metropolitan divisions the percentages are 13 and 2 respectively. In the case of rural-farm average coeffi— cients, only family income seems to manifest a large differ- ence. As in urban areas, so in the rural-nonfarm and rural- farm, the two divisions which seem to push the average value for the more metropolitan divisions above the less metropol— itan divisions are Middle Atlantic and New England. Though again.one must point out that differences between the two levels of average values are slight and that several incon— sistencies occur among indivisual divisions, it must be «granted that the data seem to support the hypothesis that 327 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um oumN Eouw quHmMMHo >HpCmUHMHCmHme woo. mmo. hmo. Hoo. NMH. vwo. omo. omo. ¢.o¢ mDHm> mmmum>¢ moo. ooo. ammo. #00. N00. *Hmo. moo. ooo. o.om HmuquU nusom ummm *moo. *HHo. H00. *H50. sumo. *moo. *omo. *fimm. m.m¢ HMHUCmU SHHOZ ummz ooo. moo. NOHH. eowH. moo. *omo. 0H0. eHoo. m.mv CHmuCCoz «moo. *moo. Hmo. *Hvo. *vmm. emoo. *mNo. emwo. N.om UHuCMHpfi Cadom Hoo. boo. ooo. *Nwo. ooo. *mmo. ammo. moo. m.mm HmuquU Cusom pmmz CmuHHomouumz mmmq mmo. mmH. mmo. ooo. mmN. mHo. omo. vmo. o.vh mCHm> mmmum>< *oHo. ammo. ammo. somo. Noo. *mNH. *mHo. *flHo. H.ho HmuquU xuuoz ummm sfimo. somv. «va. *mMH. somm. *Nwo. «00H. «HOH. m.0H oCmHmCm sz woo. HNo. mHo. «omo. «wow. HHo. moo. ammo. N.mm UHMHomm oNo. *HoN. Hoo. *mvo. OHo. emmo. eme. «mMH. o.Hm UHuCMHu¢ mHooHE CmuHHomouumz who: H H .ouumz CoHumeCmuHHomouumS N N N N N N N N R MD Hm>mH >9 mCOHmH>HQ EHMMCOZIHMHCm oomH "EHMMCOCIHMHCH .CoHumuHCmuHHomoume mo Hm>mH an mCOHmH>Ho now musuusuum HmHUOm muHCCEEOU UCm mUCMCHEoo CmuHHomouumE mo ANHV mquHonmmoo COHHMHmHHoo HmoHOIOHmN .mm mHQmB It‘l.l*alsF(.(ll1\1\ll*(F‘ u( INI5\ I’- l‘ ’1. f!‘ or E 0' u. u {\ ( PI\ 1‘ \7 LEE rh nlul+rF r F It n.~h\y~f\lICL fox .va. 0 HQ arm. 328 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um oumN Eoum quCmMMHo mHuCMUHMHCmHme mmo. hHo. mNo. vvo. hNH. mmo. Nmo. 00H. ¢.ov mCHm> mmmnm>¢ moo. eoHo. sumo. moo. aHmH. somo. somo. eoNo. o.mm HmnquU Cusom ummm *NwH. emHo. moo. ammo. ooo. ammo. *mwo. *Hhm. m.m¢ Hmuquo CUHOZ ummz mHo. mHo. *wwo. *mvo. moo. Noo. ooo. *Nvo. m.m¢ CHmuCCOS Noo. ooo. *mmo. «omo. *mmw. woo. Noo. HoHo. N.om UHHCmHuC Cusom *mHo. somo. ooo. *ovo. ooo. «mOH. Homo. ewho. m.mm Hmuquo Cusom ummz CmuHHommwumE mmmq moo. omo. mmo. Hmo. ooN. mmo. mmo. NvH. o.¢n mCHm> mmmum>¢ ooo. Hoo. *mmo. *HHo. Hoo. *mmo. emoo. *mwo. H.ho HmuquU Cuuoz ummm ooo. *Nmo. *HBH. *mom. *hmv. «omo. *mmo. *mmH. m.om UCMHmCm 3oz HHo. ooo. mNo. ammo. *mNo. mNo. xmvo. xde. N.mH UHMHumm Hoo. ammo. woo. *Nmo. «NNH. moo. *Nmo. emmH. w.Hm UHquHu< mHoon CmuHHomouumz who: mHH mHu hHH mHH mHH ¢HH MHH NHH .ouumz COHumeCmuHHomouumz N IN N N N N N N R mo Hm>mH an mCOHmH>HQ EummnHmusm oomH "ECMMIHMHCH .CoHumuHCMUHHomonumE mo Hm>mH an mConH>Ho How mHCuoCuum HMHUom muHCCEEOU oCm mUCMCHEOU CMHHHomouumE mo ANCV mquHUHmwmoo COHHMHmHHOU HmoHOIOHmN .aa mHnme TRUE don beh- est Cie nan. See} FIEt; in: 329 metropolitan dominance is a more important determinant of community social structure variation in the more metropol- itan divisions than the less metropolitan divisions. But to conclude the testing of this hypothesis, we must also consider the relative importance of metropolitan dominance in determining fertility behavior by the extent of metropolitan development among the divisions. Table 45 con- tains two sets of data to test the relative importance of metropolitan dominance in determining community fertility behavior: rankings of the beta coefficients from the estimated multiple regression equations and the squared zero-order correlation coefficients of fertility and metro— politan dominance. For both sets of statistics the hypoth- esized pattern is supported for urban, rural-nonfarm and rural-farm areas, although the pattern is clearer using the zero—order correlation coefficients than the beta coeffi- cients. Compared with the influence of metropolitan domi— nance on community social structure, metropolitan dominance seems to have a greater effect on fertility. On the average metropolitan dominance explains 17 percent of the variation in fertility in urban areas of the more metropolitan divi- sions, 25 percent in the rural-nonfarm areas, and 12 percent in the rural—farm areas. In the less metropolitan divisions the average coefficient values are 6, 5, and 2 percent re- spectively. For the comparison of the beta coefficients, again the average values of ranks for metropolitan dominance Table 45. 330 Rank of metropolitan dominance by relative impor- tance in accounting for variation in fertility based on beta coefficients and zero-order corre- lation coefficient of metropolitan dominance and fertility for divisions by level of metropolitan— ization, by residence: 1960 Rank of Metropolitan 2 Dominance by rlY Divisions by Beta Coef. Level of Metro- % politanization Metro. Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF More Metropolitan Middle Atlantic 81.8 1 l l .158* .291* .155* Pacific 79.2 3 5 4 .181* .156* .076* New England 70.3 5 5 8 .240* .457* .203* E. N. Central 67.1 2 l 3 .081* .102* .061* Average Value 74.6 2.8 3.0 4.0 .165 .252 .124 Less Metropolitan W. S. Central 53.5 5 7 5 .086* .015* .000 South Atlantic 50.2 6 3 l .070* .045* .033* Mountain 48.8 5 2 6 .095* .138* .025* W. N. Central 43.3 3 3 4 .065* .027* .038* E. S. Central 36.0 5 2 5 .001 .001 .002 Average Value 46.4 4.8 3.4 4.2 .063 .045 .020 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. it le CC 331 indicate that it is on the average a more important variable in determining fertility variation among the more metropol- itan divisions than the less metropolitan divisions. The average rank of metropolitan dominance in urban areas is 2.8, rural—nonfarm 3.0, and rural-farm 4.0 for the more metropol- itan divisions, and 4.8, 3.4, and 4.2 respectively for the less metropolitan divisions. There are inconsistencies, of course, when individual divisions are compared rather than average values of the two categories of divisions. Further- more, the two sets of data, beta and zero-order correlation coefficients, do not portray the same patterns. For example, the zero-order correlation coefficients for New England are highest among the divisions, but in terms of the rankings by beta coefficients metropolitan dominance is relatively less important for New England compared with the other more metro- politan divisions. Beta coefficients reflect the effect of metropolitan dominance on fertility with the influence of the other independent variables partialled. The zero-order corre— lation coefficients, of course, do not control for other variables. Hence this difference perhaps explains the incon- sistency for the two types of data. Nevertheless on the average the hypothesis is supported so that we may conclude that metropolitan dominance is relatively more important in the more metropolitan divisions in accounting for fertility variation, as well as community social structure, in both rural and urban areas, than in the less metropolitan divi- sions. en ti 111 i1 16 332 Hypothesis 6 In the more metropolitan geographic divisions, size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center will be more important in accounting for variation in community fertility behavior, in both urban and rural hinterlands, than local community social structure, when controlling for the influence of metropolitan centers; in less met- ropolitan geographic divisions, local community social structure will be more important in accounting for vari- ation in community fertility behavior than size and distance of a dominating metropolitan center. We have considered previously the competing influ- ence of metropolitan dominance and local community condi- tions in determining intercommunity variation in fertility behavior, but this consideration did not include the effects of differential levels of metropolitanization among the divisions. The comparison in a previous hypothesis was primarily among the residential hinterland types, i.e., urban vs. rural. It was anticipated that metropolitan dom— inance would be more important in determining fertility levels in urban hinterland communities than local community conditions, but less important in rural communities. The hypothesis was not supported. The comparison being made in this section, however, is inter-divisional rather than inter- residential. In the previous hypothesis it was found that metropolitan dominance is more important in determining urban and rural fertility behavior in the more metropolitan divisions. But is metropolitan dominance so important in these divisions that it overshadows the effects of local community social structure? Furthermore in the less metro— politan divisions is metropolitan dominance so low in 333 importance that local community social structure exceeds it in determining fertility variation in urban and rural hinter— land communities? According to the average rank values of the beta coefficients for each of the independent variables presented in Table 46, the hypothesis seems to be true. Comparing the urban hinterlands of the two categories of divisions, metro- politan dominance on the average is more important in accounting for fertility variation than community social structure in the more metropolitan divisions, but exceeded in the less metropolitan divisions by ever—married females ages 15-24 and education. The average rank of metropolitan dominance in urban areas for the more metropolitan divisions is 2.8, but only 4.8 for the less metropolitan divisions. Comparing rural—nonfarm areas, metropolitan dominance shares first place in relative importance with family income for the more metropolitan divisions but is exceeded by education in the less metropolitan divisions. For rural—farm areas, though the average rank values of metropolitan dominance are very similar for the two categories of divisions, in the more metropolitan divisions on the average metropolitan dominance is more important in determining fertility variation but in the less metropolitan divisions it is exceeded by education, employment of farmers and farm managers, and employment of farm laborers and foremen. The consistency of education as a more important determinant of intercommunity fertility 334 .CHmuCCOZ oCm .HmHquU Cusom ummz .HmuquU Cusom ummm .UHuCMHud Cpsom .HmnquU Cuuoz ummz mUCHUCH mCOHmH>HU CmuHHomouumE mmmqee .UHMHUmm oCm .Hmuquo Cuuoz ummm .UHuCMHu4 mHooHE .UCmHmCm BmZ moCHUCH mConH>Ho CmuHHomouumE muoze o.m ¢.H «.6 m.H m.m m.m Amxo emImN mmm mmHmEmm e.¢ o.e m.N m.¢ m.m m.m A xv «NumH mmm mmHmsmm musuosuum mmm UHCmMHmmEmQ o.m N.e o.m m.¢ m.¢ m.H AHxv ucmsHoHCEm mHmsmm m.m m.m m.m m.m o.m m.m onv mEOUCH mHmEmm mmHHHCCuHQmmo m>HHMCHmuH¢ m.meB N.m N.m o.m m.m o.m m.¢ Amxv msoocH HHHEmm a.m o.N m.N m.¢ o.a m.m Aexo aoHumoswm msumpm UHEOCoomIOHUom o.m m.m N.m m.m o.m m.m Amxv CmEmuom oCm mHmCOQMH Eumm m.m m.m m.m m.m m.m m.m ANXV mummmsz Eumm UCm mHmEHmm mCoHummono HmusuHsoHum< CH quENmHmam N.a v.m m.e o.¢ o.m m.N Aon mommaHsoo cmpHHomouumz mm mzm QHD mm mzm nub mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH quHonmmoo mumm mo quHonmmoo mumm mo mem mmmum>< MCmm mmmum>¢ mConH>HQ mCOHmH>Ho eeCmuHHomouuwz mmmH eCmuHHomouumz who: oomH "mUCmonmu ma oCm mCOHmH>Ho mo CoHuMNHCmuHHom louumE mo Hm>mH >9 mquHonwmoo mumm >3 omusmmmfi muHHHqum CH COHuwHHm> How mCHuCCooom CH moCmuHomEH m>HHMHmH an meQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH mo meH mmwnm>< .ov mHQmB 335 variation in all three residential sectors of the less metro- politan divisions is to be especially noted, whereas for the more metropolitan divisions the most important determinant is distance and size of a dominating metropolitan center. Hypothesis 7 The impact of community social structure and metropol- itan dominance on fertility behavior will manifest fewer differences when comparing the same type of hinterland communities (urban or rural) on an inter-divisional basis than when comparing different types of hinterland communities (urban vs. rural) on an intra—divisional basis. The basic theoretical assumption underlying this hypothesis is that metropolitan centers exert a differential impact on the different residential hinterland communities within their metropolitan regions. As metropolitanization continues to emerge as a key process in the determination of intercommunity variation patterns, we should expect to find that differences will increase among residential hinterland communities. Though our analysis focuses primarily on fac— tors which influence fertility behavior, it is possible to test this differential impact hypothesis by statistical testing. We have estimated multiple regression equations for each of the residential sectors of all geographic divi— 8ions of the nation. In each equation fertility is the dependent variable and indices of metropolitan dominance and Community social structure are the independent varibles. By means of the multiple comparison test it is possible to determine whether each of the independent variables has the 336 same effect on fertility in the different resiential sectors of each of the divisions. An example of the kind of ques- tion posed in the application of the multiple comparison test is whether the effect of metropolitan dominance upon fertility is the same for the rural-farm communities as for the urban communities of a given division. The multiple comparison test involves the comparison of the effects of the partial regression coefficients on fertility in two different multiple regression equations. Hence the test can be employed to determine whether there is a statistically significant difference between only two partial regression coefficients at a time. For each independent variable rep— resented in the multiple regression equation we may for any division make comparisons of rural-farm vs. rural—nonfarm, rural-farm vs. urban, and rural—nonfarm vs. urban. If the hypothesis is at all true, i.e., if metropolitan centers do exert a differential impact on the residential hinterland communities, we should eXpect to find significant differences between residential sectors for most of the partial regres- sion coefficients reflecting the effects of the independent variables on fertility behavior. Furthermore, given differ- ent rates of metropolitanization among the divisions, a sig- nificant difference should be found between partial regres- sion coefficients more frequently for the more metropolitan divisions. 337 In addition, however, the multiple comparison test can be employed to determine whether the independent vari- ables exert a differential impact on fertility among the geographic divisions of the nation. An example of the kind of question posed by this test would be whether the effect of metropolitan dominance on fertility is the same for the urban communities of one division as for the urban commu— nities of another division. In contrast to the first com— parison described above, i.e., an inter-residential compar- ison for a given division, the comparison called for here is an inter-divisional one within the same residential sector. The theoretical framework of this study suggests that as metropolitanization emerges as a dominant process within the nation, that divisional differences will disappear while residential differences will be enhanced. If this observa- tion is valid, after applying the multiple comparison test at the two levels suggested above, i.e., inter—divisional and inter-residential, we should expect to find a pattern of significant differences for the inter-residential comparisons but homogeneity for the inter-divisional comparisons. Hence this test is a test of the differentiating effects of metro- politan centers on residential hinterland communities. First, let us consider the results of the multiple comparison tests between residential sectors. The results of these statistical tests are given in Table 47. Overall it appears that there is enough evidence to assert that there 3EH3 Table 47. Summary of results for multiple comparison tests among residential sectors of conterminous United States and divisions f ‘——‘ Independent Variables Residential Sectors Compared for Nation and Divisions X1 X2 X3 X4 X5 X6 x7 x8 x9 UNITED STATES Rura -Parm vs. Rural-Nonfarm 0 0 1 1 1 l l 1 0 Rural-Farm vs. Urban 1 0 1 1 l 0 l 1 1 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 New En land RuraE-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm O 0 l l 0 1 l 1 0 Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 1 l o 0 1 1 O 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 l 0 Middle Atlantic RuraIeFarm vs. Rural-Nonfarm l 1 1 1 0 1 1 O l Rural-Farm vs. Urban 1 0 l 1 0 0 l 0 l Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 l 1 l 1 1 l 1 1 East North Central Rura -Parm vs. Rural-Nonfarm 1 1 0 1 0 0 1 l O Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 0 1 1 1 0 l O 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 1 1 1 l 0 0 1 0 West North Central Rural-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm l 1 1 1 0 0 O 1 l Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 0 O 1 O 0 O O 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 0 0 O 1 0 1 O 1 1 South Atlantic Rural-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm 0 l 0 0 0 0 1 l 1 Rural-Farm vs. Urban 1 l O 1 1 0 0 1 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 0 l O l l 0 l 0 1 East South Central Rural-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm O 0 0 l 0 0 0 1 l Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 O 1 O o 0 l O O Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 O 1 0 0 1 l 0 0 West South Central Rural-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm 0 0 l l l O 0 0 1 Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 0 l l 1 O O l 1 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 0 0 1 O 0 O l 1 1 Mountain Rural-Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm O l 0 1 l 0 0 1 O Rural-Farm vs. urban 0 l O 1 0 O 0 l 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 l 0 0 0 0 l l 0 Pacific Rura -Farm vs. Rural-Nonfarm O O O 0 0 0 O O O Rural-Farm vs. Urban 0 1 O 0 1 1 0 0 0 Rural-Nonfarm vs. Urban 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 O "1" denotes that there is a significant difference between the regres- sion coefficients of the independent variable for the two sectors compared. "0" denotes that there is 29 significant difference between the regres- sion coefficients. X1 Metropolitan dominance. x6 Median female personal income X2 Percent male labor force employed in 1959‘ as farmers and farm managers. x7 Percent females, age 14 and over, x3 Percent male labor force employed employed. as farm laborers and foremen. x8 Percent ever-married females, x4 Median years school completed by ages 15'44' who are age 15'24° males and females, age 25 and X9 Percent ever-married females, over. ages 15-44, who are age 25-34. x5 Median family income in 1959. 339 are consistently significant differences among the residen- tial sectors to support the hypothesis. Differential effects for all_three comparisons occur frequently among the various divisions: farm laborers and foremen, female income, and female employment in New England; metropolitan dominance, farm laborers and foremen, education, female employment and females ages 25-34 in Middle Atlantic; education in East North Central and West North Central; farmers and farm man- agers in South Atlantic and Mountain: farm laborers and foremen in West South Central. Few differences occur in East South Central, the least metropolitan division, and unexpectantly in Pacific, a highly metropolitan division. Education shows the most frequent occurrence of a signif- icant differential impact in comparing the residential sec- tors, followed by females ages 15-24, farmers and farm man- agers, farm laborers and foremen, and female employment. It is difficult to conclude which residential hinter— land contrast indicates the more frequent significant compar— isons. It appears to be the comparison of the rural-nonfarm and urban sectors. Interestingly for this comparison, the differences seem to concentrate more consistently in the more metropolitan divisions, which more accurately is an urban-suburban comparison rather than a rural—urban compar- ison. For the rural-farm vs. urban comparison education indicates most frequently a substantiation of the differen- tial effects hypothesis while metropolitan dominance, female s ig the var feI the 340 employment and females ages 25-34 least frequently reveal significant differences of their effects on fertility. For the rural—nonfarm vs. urban comparison the independent variables which most often indicate differential effects on fertility are farmers and farm managers, female employment, and females ages 15—24. In the case of comparing the rural sectors the variables most frequently revealing a signif— icant difference in their impact on fertility are education and females ages 15-24. Family income, female income, and metropolitan dominance indicate few significant differences for this residential comparison. To summarize, the differential impact of the inde- pendent variables on fertility between residential hinter- land areas is substantial. These differences are especially pronounoaiamong the more metropolitan divisions, although of these divisions one exception seems to be the Pacific. For this division the rural sectors appear to be quite homoge- neous with respect to the impact of the independent vari- ables on fertility. Greater contrasts for this division are primarily rural vs. urban. It could be in the case of the Pacific division that the percentage of population residing in metropolitan areas is deceptive of its actual level of metropolitanization. Let us at this point turn to the inter—divisional comparisons within the residential sectors. The results of the multiple comparison tests between divisions are provided in ta si a: CE OC fc fa e1 ()4 C l f1 341 in Table 48. It is obvious from a quick perusal of this table that the independent variables reveal relatively similar effects on fertility among the divisions. In com- paring these results with the inter-residential comparisons we conclude immediately that the seventh hypothesis of this chapter is substantiated. The more significant evidence of differentiation, then, is among residential hinterlands, not among divisions. Interestingly most of the significant cases of differential impact of the independent variables occur within the urban areas. The differences exist mostly for the socio—economic status variables of education and family income. The few cases of significant differential effects in the rural sectors appear to be female employment and metropolitan dominance in rural—nonfarm areas and female employment and females ages 15-24 in rural-farm areas. Interestingly relatively few differences between independent variables occur in the comparisons of the more metropolitan divisions. More frequently the significant contrasts occur when comparing the impact of the independent variables on fertility among the less metropolitan divisions and as well between the less and more metropolitan divisions. Our conclusion for this hypothesis, then, is one of confirmation. In accord with metropolitan dominance theory, divisional differences are disappearing while residential hinterland differences are becoming prominent. This is further supported when considering the results of the multiple o i w [T “C .’ . 9 Li :. Ea: Ea: Ea! Ea: Ea: Eel 3:233: «warns!» ,v (DUDCDU) 0000 ('1 P11 [II 0! w (11' P411 Table 48. 342 Summary of results for multiple comparison tests between divisions of contermi- nous United States by residential sector Divisions Compared for Residential Sectors Independent Variables X ... x3 X X X X URBAN England England England England England England England England V3. V8. V8. V8. V8. V8. VB. vs. Middle Atlantic East North Central West North Central South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic V8. V8. V8. V8. V3. V3. V8. East North Central West North Central South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific East East East East East East West West West West West North North North North North North North North North North North Central Central Central Central Central Central Central Central Central Central Central V8. V3. V8. V8. V8. V8. V8. V3. V8. V8. V8. West North Central South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific South Atlantic VS. East South Central South Atlantic South Atlantic South Atlantic East East East West West South Central vs. West South Central vs. West South Central vs. Mountain vs. Pacific South Central vs. Mountain South Central vs. Pacific South Central vs. Mountain South Central vs. Pacific Mountain vs. Pacific RURAL-NONFARM New New New New New New New New England England England England England England England England VB. VB. VI. V8. V3. V3. V8. V3. Middle Atlantic East North Central west North Central South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Middle Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic Atlantic V8. VI. V8. V8. V8. V8. V8. East North Central West North Central South Atlantic East South Central West South Central Mountain Pacific 0 00 000 0000 OOOOH 0000H0 0000000 00000000 0000000 0H000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0000000 HHO0P000 0000000 00000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0000000 l-‘l-‘P-‘l-‘OHOH 0000000 00000000 0H00000 00000000 0 00 OO-‘H OHOO CPD-'00 HHPHO—‘H 0HH0000 0H000000 0 00 000 0H00 CHOP-‘0 0000I-‘H 0H0000H 00000000 0000000 00000000 0 00 H00 0000 000PH 000000 0000000 00000000 0000000 00000000 0 00 HOP 0000 0000-‘0 000000 0000000 00000000 0000000 00000000 0 00 000 0000 00HOH 00POH0 000000.‘ 00000000 0000000 00000000 0 00 GOP oor-oo COD-‘00 00P000 0000000 00000000 0000000 00000000 m.r ~.w «so Alw ALL _,_ HKV Asu a\; .x. To A.. TL .5; r u ... H.L up; A. H u 343 Table 48—-Continued Independent Variables Divisions Compared for Residential Sectors X X X X X X ... X N 3 4 5 6 7 X (D East North Central vs. West North Central East North Central vs. South Atlantic East North Central vs. East South Central East North Central vs. West South Central East North Central vs. Mountain East North Central vs. Pacific West North Central vs. South Atlantic West North Central vs. East South Central West North Central vs. West South Central West North Central vs. Mountain West North Central vs. Pacific South Atlantic vs. East South Central South Atlantic vs. West South Central South Atlantic vs. Mountain South Atlantic vs. Pacific East South Central vs. West South Central East South Central vs. Mountain East South Central vs. Pacific West South Central vs. Mountain West South Central vs. Pacific H OH 000 0000 0P000 000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0 00 000 OHOO 00000 0000D-‘0 0 00 000 0000 000t-‘0 000H00 0 00 HOD-J 000R OPOHP COCO-'00 Mountain vs. Pacific RURAL-FARM New England vs. Middle Atlantic New England vs. East North Central New England vs. West North Central New England vs. South Atlantic New England vs. East South Central New England vs. West South Central New England vs. Mountain New England vs. Pacific Middle Atlantic vs. East North Central Middle Atlantic vs. West North Central Middle Atlantic vs. South Atlantic Middle Atlantic vs. East South Central Middle Atlantic vs. West South Central Middle Atlantic vs. Mountain Middle Atlantic vs. Pacific East North Central vs. West North Central East North Central vs. South Atlantic East North Central vs. East South Central East North Central vs. West South Central East North Central vs. Mountain East North Central vs. Pacific West North Central vs. South Atlantic West North Central vs. East South Central West North Central vs. West South Central West North Central vs. Mountain West North Central vs. Pacific 00000 000000 0000000 00000000 00000 000000 0000000 00000000 00000 000000 0000000 00000000 0H000 OHOOOO 0000000 00000000 COD-‘00 000000 0000000 00000000 00000 000000 0000000 00000000 000l-‘0 OHOHHO 0000000 00000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 0 00 000 0000 00000 000000 OOHOH 00H000 0000000 00000000 00000 000000 0000000 00000000 344 Table 48--Continued l Independent Variables X X X X Divisions Compared for Residential Sectors X1 X2 X3 X4 5 6 7 8 9 South Atlantic vs. East South Central 0 O 0 O 0 O l 0 0 South Atlantic vs. West South Central 0 O 0 0 1 0 0 O 0 South Atlantic vs. Mountain 0 0 0 l 0 O O 1 0 South Atlantic vs. Pacific 0 0 0 O 0 0 0 0 0 East South Central vs. West South Central 0 0 0 0 l O l J 0 East South Central vs. Mountain 0 0 0 U 0 0 a I 0 East South Central vs. Pacific 0 0 0 O 0 0 0 O 0 West South Central vs. Mountain 0 0 0 l l 0 0 l 0 West South Central vs. Pacific 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mountain vs. Pacific 0 O 0 0 0 O O O O "1" denotes that there is a significant difference between the regression coef‘ cients of the independent variable for the two divisions compared. ”0“ denotes that there is 22 significant difference between the rtJressi»n coefficients. Metropolitan dominance. Percent male labor force employed as farmers and farm managers. Percent male labor force employed as farm laborers and foremen. Median years school completed by males and females, age 25 and over. Median family income in 1959. Median female personal income in 1959. Percent females, age 14 and over, employed. Percent ever-married females, ages 15-44, who are age 15-24. Percent ever-married females, ages 15-44, who are age 25-34. ~o lrn FH D—d If) 345 comparison tests for only the more metropolitan divisions, the divisions which may be considered the models for all divisions of the nation as metropolitanization becomes a prevailing mode'of organization. Divisional differences will be superceded by differences among the residential hinterland sectors effected primarily by the differentiating influences of metropolitan centers. Summaryyof Findings Seven basic hypotheses, each emanating from a metro- politan dominance theoretical framework, have been tested against various types of data. Of these seven hypotheses, six have been substantiated and one rejected. Let us review the results of the testing of these seven hypotheses very briefly. It has been determined that community social struc- ture is a function of distance and size of a dominating met- ropolitan center. Community social structure variables highly influenced by metropolitan dominance are family in— come, employment of farmers and farm managers, and ever- married females ages 15—24, although significant correla— tions were also found for employment of farm laborers and foremen, education, and female employment. Differential impact of metropolitan dominance is supported more by the existence and degree of association with the community social structure variables than by direction of association. For education and employment of farmers and farm managers, 346 metropolitan dominance is more influential in rural hinter- land communities, but for female personal income and ever— married females ages 15-24, metropolitan dominance is more influential in urban hinterland communities. The size of the correlation coefficients suggests, however, that metro— politan dominance is not as pervasive in determining inter- community variation of social structure as expected. It has also been shown that fertility behavior is a function of both metropolitan dominance and community social structure. Differential impact of metropolitan dominance is supported only by the degree of association within the resi- dential sectors. In all sectors it is negatively associated with fertility. The only community social structure variable which supports a differential impact with respect to direc- tion of association is employment of farmers and farm man— agers. In terms of degree of association, community social structure variables which are more determinate of urban fer- tility are family income, female income, ever-married females ages 15—24 and 25-34. Community social structure variables highly influential in rural areas are employment of farmers and farm managers and education. Combined, however, the community social structure variables and metropolitan dom- inance reflect greatest influence in determining fertility variation in urban areas, lowest in rural-farm areas, and intermediate in rural-nonfarm. 347 The third hypothesis, which was also supported, was tested by means of partial and multiple-partial correlation coefficients. It was found that fertility behavior con- tinues to be significantly related to community social structure after the influence of metropolitan centers has been controlled. Employment in agricultural occupations and socio—economic status were especially important in deter- mining fertility levels in rural hinterland communities while wife's alternative opportunities and demographic age structure tend to be more influential in urban hinterland communities. The fact that the correlation coefficients of fertility and community social structure variables remained statistically significant for the most part, after metropol— itan dominance had been partialled, provides additional evidence by which to doubt the pervasiveness of metropolitan dominance in determining inter-community fertility variation. Fertility levels in urban and rural areas are the product of both metropolitan dominance and local community conditions. The fourth hypothesis of this study was not supported by the data employed. On the basis of the development of a metropolitan dominance theoretical framework it was proposed that community fertility behavior would be more a function of metropolitan dominance in urban hinterland communities, but more a function of local community social structure in rural hinterland communities. Both multiple-partial correla— tion coefficients and beta coefficients were employed to 348 determine the relative importance of metropolitan dominance and community social structure in determining urban and rural fertility variation. For urban areas it was expected that metropolitan dominance would reveal coefficients exceed- ing those for community social structure variables in deter— mining fertility variation, but that community social struc— ture coefficients would be more prominent in rural areas. The data indicated no consistent pattern in this respect. Even when considering the average rank values of the inde- pendent variables among the divisions in determining urban and rural fertility levels, it was discovered that in all residential sectors a community social structure variable exceeded metropolitan dominance for relative importance in determining fertility variation. The most important commu- nity social structure variable in urban areas was ever- married females ages 15—24 and in both rural sectors, educa— tion. The fifth and sixth hypotheses are similar to the previous hypotheses but different in that they considered the possibility that patterns of association among the dependent and independent variables were blurred by the existence of different levels of metropolitanization among the divisions of the nation. In the testing of these two hypotheses some control over the differential metropolitan— ization of the divisions was attempted by subdividing the divisions into two categories: (1) those indicating a 349 percentage of population residing in metropolitan areas above the level of the nation and (2) those with percentage metropolitan below the level of the nation. It was expected, then, that the patterns predicted on the basis of metropol- itan dominance theory would hold true more for the more metropolitan divisions than the less metropolitan divisions. It was determined that metropolitan dominance is a more important determinant of community social structure in the more metropolitan divisions than the less metropolitan divi— sions in all three residential sectors. On the average cor— relation coefficients between metropolitan dominance and community social structure were higher for the more metropol— itan divisions. This pattern was true for all the average coefficients in the rural-nonfarm sector, six of the eight coefficients in the rural-farm, and five of the eight in the urban sector. The pattern of more relative importance of metropolitan dominance in the more metropolitan divisions was much stronger when considering the influence of metropol- itan dominance on urban, rural—nonfarm, and rural—farm fer- tility levels. Though inconsistencies in the predicted pattern do occur in the comparison of individual divisions by level of metropolitanization, it appears that a universal metropolitan dominance pattern has not as yet emerged among all divisions of the nation and, therefore, level of metro- politanization is a significant factor to consider in explor- ing further hypotheses derived from metropolitan dominance theory. 350 The sixth hypothesis attempted to test a more specific pattern in the dominating influence of metropolitan centers on their hinterlands. This hypothesis is a repeat of the fourth hypothesis, which was rejected, but with the added factor of level of metropolitanization among the divi- sions somewhat controlled. The finding of this test indi— cates that in all residential sectors metropolitan dominance is on the average more important in determining fertility levels than community social structure in the more metropol— itan divisions, but superceded in the less metropolitan divisions by various community social structure variables. Though previous results suggested the questioning of the pervasiveness of metropolitan centers as organizing agents of hinterland inter-community variation for the nation, the finding here suggests the reinstatement of this pattern par— ticularly for the divisions of the nation which are more advanced in the development of metropolitanization. The data indicated that hinterlands of all three residential types do come more under the dominance of metropolitan cen- ters than the influence of local conditions in the more metropolitan divisions. Apparently in the less metropolitan divisions local community conditions still exert a consider- able impact in determining inter—community variation in urban, rural—nonfarm, and rural—farm hinterlands compared with metropolitan dominance. 351 Finally the verification of the seventh and last hypothesis of this study also adds considerably to the sup- port of metropolitan dominance theory. In the chapter deal- ing with the theoretical framework of this study, it was mentioned that one of the primary points which distinguishes urban dominance and metropolitan dominance theory has to do with the pattern of effects exerted by cities upon their hinterland region. Urban dominance theory predicts the disappearance of urban and rural residential differences on the basis of the assumption that cities exert a homogeneous impact on hinterland communities. Metropolitan dominance theory, on the other hand, leads to the conclusion that urban-rural differences will persist primarily due to the differential impact of metropolitan centers upon hinterland communities. By means of the multiple comparison test it was possible to test whether the differential effects pat— tern among residential sectors of metropolitan hinterland regions was true with respect to the comparison of the effects of the independent variables employed in the multi- ple regression equation on fertility variation. It was found that among the divisions of the nation, the indepen— dent variables in many cases do exert differential effects on fertility in comparing the residential sectors. Hence we conclude that fertility differences do exist between the residential areas of the divisions, though these differences were shown to be in terms of the pattern of association of 352 the independent variables in determining fertility levels themselves. In other words, this means that a factor, such as education, has a significantly different effect on fertil— ity in urban areas than rural areas. It is suggested, then, that the chief cause of this pattern of differential effects is the influence of metropolitan centers on the different types of residential hinterlands. The fact that the pattern of differential effects between residential sectors was found to be more pronounced in the more metropolitan divi- sions provides added support to this particular hypothesis derived from metropolitan dominance theory. Furthermore, the finding that few differences exist for the effect of the independent variables on fertility in the comparison of the divisions also adds support to the metropolitan dominance theory. What this implies, of course, is that divisional and regional differences, which were formerly significant sources of areal differences within the nation are giving way in the face of the increasingly greater influence of metropolitan centers in determining inter-community and interareal variation in the nation. This is supported by the finding that similarity of effects on fertility by the independent variables is to be found more clearly among the more metropolitan divisions, the divisions in which the most support for the differential impact among residential sec- tors was expected to be found. In conclusion, we have found that fertility behavior is influenced both by distance and size of a dominating 353 metropolitan center and community social structure. In speaking of community social structure, we have in mind the influence of local conditions indigenous to the respective hinterland communities, since inter-community social struc- ture variation produced by the influence of metropolitan centers had been partialled. Among all the divisions it appeared that local community conditions exert a consider- able influence on fertility behavior in all residential sec- tors, more than the metropolitan dominance variable. However, in considering the more metropolitan divisions distinct from the less metropolitan divisions, it was found that metropol— itan dominance is a very important determinant of community social structure variation and fertility behavior. Further- more for these same more metropolitan divisions, it was found that in all residential sectors metropolitan dominance ex- ceeded community social structure in determining fertility levels, whereas in the less metropolitan divisions education and females age 15-24 exceeded metropolitan dominance in rural and urban hinterland communities respectively. A dif- ferentiating process is operative among the residential sec- tors, especially among the more metropolitan divisions, where— as divisional differences are diminishing. It is concluded that the discovery of such a pattern is proof of a gradual emergence of metropolitan centers as the primary organizing agent of inter-community hinterland variation. As all divi- sions continue to become more metropolitan, the influence of metropolitan centers will likewise increase. CHAPTER VI REFLECTIONS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH New approaches to the study of differential fertil— ity are definitely needed in demographic research today. It is my hope that if any contribution has been made by this thesis, it has been in the direction of demonstrating a new approach to the study of the urban-rural fertility differen- tial, or for that matter, any of the fertility differentials. Indeed the prediction by many demographers that the gap between urban and rural fertility levels in the United States is disappearing is not sufficient justification to end our investigations in this area. Rather new approaches, methodological and theoretical, must be sought in order to increase our understanding of the true and complex dynamics of fertility. Methodologically the present study has attempted to point out the inadequacies of such conventional approaches to differential fertility as trend analysis and the "aggre- gate" approach. Longitudinal and cross-sectional analyses which attempt merely to document whether there exists a sig- nificant association between various socio-economic and demographic variables and fertility are not sensitive enough 354 355 to represent accurately and comprehensively current differen— tial fertility patterns. The degree of association as well as the relative importance of such variables in determining fertility patterns should be investigated also. Although there are other methodological approaches available which could solve such problems, the present study found a dis— tributive approach operationalized in the form of multiple regression analysis extremely valuable for such purposes. Employing new methodological techniques, however, does not necessitate a search for new sources of data. Though a major source of information for studies employing trend analysis and the aggregate approach has been the census, and though the vogue in fertility analysis has been large sample surveys, the present study has attempted to demon- strate that census data, likewise, are very amenable to entirely different methodological approaches such as multiple regression analysis. Methodological ingenuity and experimentation are urgently needed in differential fertil— ity analysis at a time when conventional methods seem to be providing only fruitless repetition and little new knowledge. Theoretically we must also turn in new directions. Differential fertility theory has been as deficient as its methodology. Indeed there is much evidence of emerging new middle range theories of differential fertility and these are contributing much to a bridging of the gap which formerly existed between "theory" and "empirical data." Demographic 356 transition theory, which for many years served as puny proof that demographers were interested in theory, has undergone repeated attack. Many of its generalizing principles have been shown to be inadequate to explain current as well as past fertility patterns. It has failed to generate new hypotheses. In addition this thesis has attempted to demon— strate that the theory itself, when applied to the current situation in American society, leads to inaccurate and ques— tionable conclusions. Implicit in the demographic transi- tion theory is the concept of urban dominance. It is this concept which has led many researchers to the conclusion that the urban—rural fertility differential is doomed to dissolution. The present study has argued that urban domi— nance is not an adequate description of the dynamics of American society, but metropolitan dominance is. It is suggested that metropolitan dominance theory must somehow be incorporated into the framework of demographic transition theory if the latter is to continue as a useful theoretical framework by which to understand currently modern complex societies. By substituting metropolitan dominance theory for urban dominance theory in differential fertility analysis, new questions and problems are produced and new dimensions for further research are uncovered. But, of course, there have been deficiencies in the manner by which metropolitan dominance theory has been researched as well. Many re— searchers apparently have failed to perceive that these two 357 theoretical positions, urban and metropolitan dominance, lead to conflicting conclusions. This oversight has been due primarily to an overemphasis on the gradient principle and an equally underemphasis of the differentiating prin— ciple. The gradient principle, it has been noted previously, is an element common to both urban dominance and metropol— itan dominance theory. Hence the successful testing of this principle has usually found the researcher confused as to whether his findings actually supported one theory or the other. All too frequently the researcher would choose to avoid the issue altogether rather than deal with it directly. It is the differentiating principle, however, which is the distinguishing characteristic of the two theories, but little research has been performed directed by this prin- ciple. In the application of metropolitan dominance theory to differential fertility analysis, it is the differentiating principle which has lead to the conclusion that urban and rural fertility levels may not eventually converge. Even if the levels themselves do converge, on the basis of the ideas presented on differential fertility in this thesis, it is possible that the patterns of differential fertility found in urban and rural areas may not necessarily resemble each other. Much more research, then, is needed to determine the differentiating effects of metropolitan centers on the hinter— land communities comprising the metropolitan region. The present study attempted to do just that and the findings 358 seem to indicate that urban and rural differential fertility patterns are distinct, especially in the more metropolitan geographic divisions of the nation. In a sense, then, the findings of this study have lent some support to the "pro" side of the current argument as to whether the "urban" and "rural" categories provide a meaningful distinction in the analysis of American society. The present study has assumed, of course, that one of the main dimensions of the differen- tiating effect of metropolitan dominance on hinterland com— munities is along urban-rural lines. The findings of this study seem to bear this out, although, obviously, more research on this problem is needed. I am not wholly satis- fied with the design of this thesis in testing this question, however. A weakness of the present study, it seems to me, is the failure to consider the differentiating effects of metropolitan dominance for areas smaller than a geographic division. It seems to me that the next logical step is to research the hypotheses of this study for individual metro- politan regions. At this level it would be possible to contrast the differentiating effect of metropolitan domi- nance on urban and rural hinterland communities even within the same distance zone from a given metropolitan center. In such a study, of course, differential fertility patterns would provide only one of numerous dimensions which should be investigated to determine the differentiating effect of metropolitan dominance on urban and rural hinterland commu- nities. In addition, other classification schemes for 359 hinterland communities must also be devised other than the traditional urban—rural categories. In conclusion, I wish to point out that these are only a few of the problems which could profitably be re— searched in the future. As the pattern is in any intensive struggle with a given problem, I find this study gives rise to many more questions than it answers. In fact I am not sure myself that the answers which have been presented in this thesis are valid. I do not intend, however, to follow the example of Malthus and spend the rest of my life produc— ing improved editions of the same old, overworked ideas. If the ideas presented in this thesis are of any value, they should lead to the production of even fresher ideas. BIBLIOGRAPHY Abu-Lughod, Janet. "Urban—Rural Differences as a Function of the Demographic Transition: Egyptian Data and an Analytical Model," American Journal of Sociologyi LXIX (March, 1964), 476-90. Anderson, Theodore R., and Jane Collier. "Metropolitan Dominance and the Rural Hinterland," Rural Sociology, XXI (June, 1956), 152-57. Barclay, George W. Techniques of Population Analysis. New York: John Wiley, 1958. Bash, Wendell. "Differential Fertility in Madison County, New York, 1865," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXIII (April, 1955), 161-86. . "Changing Birth Rates in Developing America: New York State, 1840—1875," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XLI (April, 1963), 161-82. Beegle, J. Allan. "Social Structure and Changing Fertility of the Farm Population," Rural SociologX. XXXI, No. 4 (December, 1966), 415-27. Blake, Judith. "Ideal Family Size among White Americans: A Quarter Century of Evidence," Demography, III, No. l (1966), 154-73. Blalock, Hubert M., Jr. Social Statistics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1960. Bogue, Donald J. The Structure of the Metropolitan Commu— nity. Ann Arbor: Horace H. Rackham School of Graduate Studies, University of Michigan, 1950. _*_______ “Urbanism in the United States, 1950," American Journal of SociologX; LX (March, 1955), 471—86. . "Population Distribution," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Population. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959, pp. 383-99. , and Dorothy L. Harris. Comparative Population and Urban Research Via Multiple Regression and Covariance Analysis. Oxford, Ohio: Scripps Foundation, Miami University, 1954. 360 361 Bogue, Donald J., and James A. Palmore. "Some Empirical and Analytic Relations among Demographic Fertility Measures, with Regression Models for Fertility Estimation," Demography, I, No. l (1964), 316-38. Brownlee, K. A. Statistical Theory and Methodology in Science and Engineerihg. New York: John Wiley, 1960. Brunner, Edmund deS., and J. H. Kolb. Rural Social Trends. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1933, Ch. 5. Campbell, Arthur A. "Design and Scope of the 1960 Study of Growth of American Families," in C. V. Kiser, Research in Family Plannihg. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 167-83. Comhaire, Jean, and Werner J. Cahnman. How Cities Grow. Madison, New Jersey: The Floram Park Press, 1959. Cowgill, Donald 0. "Transition Theory as General Population Theory," Social Forces, XLI (March, 1963), 270-74. Davis, Kingsley. "The World Demographic Transition," The Annals, CCXXXVII (January, 1945), 1—11. . The Human Society. New York: Macmillan, 1949. . "The Sociology of Demographic Behavior," in Robert K. Merton, Leonard Broom, and Leonard S. Cottrell, Jr., Sociolognyodgy; Problems and Prospects. New YOrk: Basic Books, 1959, pp. 309-33. , and Judith Blake. "Social Structure and Fertility: An Analytical Framework," Economic Development and Cultural Change, IV (1956), 211-35. Dinkel, Robert M. "Occupation and Fertility in the United States," American Sociological Review, XVII (April, 1952), 178-83. "Fertility in Mid-Century America," Eugenics Quarterly, III (March, 1956), 22-31. Duncan, Otis Dudley. "Fertility of the Village Population in Pennsylvania, 1940," Social Forces, XXVIII (March, 1950), 304-9. . "Note on Farm Tenancy and Urbanization," Journal of Farm Economics, XXXVIII, No. 4 (November, 1956), 1043-47. D1 Fe F] P: 362 Duncan, Otis Dudley. "Gradients of Urban Influence on the Rural Population," The Midwest Sociologist, XVIII (Winter, 1956), 27-30. . "Human Ecology and Population Studies," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Stugy of Population. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959, pp. 678-716. . "From Social System to Ecosystem," Sociological Inguiry, XXXI (Spring, 1961), 140-49. . "Residential Areas and Differential Fertility," Eugenics Quarterly, XI (June, 1964), 82—89. . "Farm Background and Differential Fertility," Demography, II (1965), 240-49. , Ray P. Cuzzort, and Beverly Duncan. Statistical Geography. Glencoe: The Free Press, 1961. , and Beverly Davis. "An Alternative to Ecological Correlation," American Sociological Review, XVIII (1953), 665-66. , and A. J. Reiss, Jr. Social Characteristics of Urban and Rural Communities, 1950. New York: John Wiley, 1956. , and Leo Schnore. "Cultural, Behavioral, and Ecological Perspectives in the Study of Social Organiza- tion," American Journal of Sociology, XLV (September, 1959), 132-46. Feldman, Arnold S., and Charles Tilly. "The Interaction of Social and Physical Space," American Sociological Review, XXV, No. 6 (December, 1960), 877—84. Firey, Walter, Charles P. Loomis, and J. Allan Beegle. "The Fusion of Urban and Rural," in Jean Labatat and Wheaton J. Lane, HighWays in Our National Life: A Symposium. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1950, pp. 154-63. Reprinted in P. K. Hatt and A. J. Reiss, Jr., Cities and Society. 2nd ed. Glencoe: The Free Press, 1957, pp. 214—22. Freedman, Deborah. "The Relation of Economic Status to Fertility," American Economic Review, LIII (June, 1963), 414-26. Freedman, Ronald. "The Sociology of Human Fertility," Current Sociology, X—XI, No. 2 (1961-62), 35—119. 363 Freedman, Ronald. "American Studies of Family Planning and Fertility: A Review of Major Trends and Issues," in C. V. Kiser, Research in Family Planning. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1962, pp. 211-27. , and Deborah Freedman. "Farm-Related Elements in the Nonfarm Population," Rural Sociology, XXI (March, 1956), 50-61. , David Goldberg, and Doris Slesinger. "Current Fertility Expectations of Married Couples in the United States," Population Index, XXIX (October, 1963), 366-91. , David Goldberg, and Doris Slesinger. "Fertility Expectations in the United States: 1963," Population Index, XXX (April, 1964), 171-75. , and Doris P. Slesinger. "Fertility Differentials for the Indigenous Non—Farm Population of the United States," Population Studies, XV (November, 1961), 161-73. , P. K. Whelpton, and A. A. Campbell. Family Plan— ning, Sterilipy and Population Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1959. Gini, C. "The Cyclical Rise and Fall of Population," in Population, Harris Foundation Lectures. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1929. Goldberg, David. "The Fertility of Two Generation Urbanites," Population Studies, XII (March, 1959), 214-22. . "Another Look at the Indianapolis Fertility Data," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXVIII (January, 1960), 23-36. ' . "Some Recent Developments in American Fertility Research," in National Bureau of Economic Research, oomographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries. Princeton: University of Princeton Press, 1960, pp. 137- 51. . "Fertility and Fertility Differentials: Some Observations on Recent Changes in the United States," in M. C. Sheps and J. C. Ridley, Public Health and Population Change. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1965. Goldsmith, Harold F., and James H. Copp. "Metropolitan Dominance and Agriculture," Rural SociologY. XXIX, No. 4 (December, 1964), 385-95. 364 Goldstein, Sidney. "Changing Patterns of Fertility in Norristown, Pennsylvania, 1920-1950," Social Forces, XXXIV (October, 1955), 72-76. , and Kurt B. Mayer. "Residence and Status Differ- ences in Fertility," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, LXIII, No. 3 (July, 1965), 291-310. Goodman, Leo A. "Ecological Regression and Behavior of Individuals," American Sociological Review, XVIII (1953), 663-64. . "Some Alternatives to Ecological Correlation," American Sociologlcal Review, XXIV (1959), 610-25. , and William H. Kruskal. "Measures of Association for Cross-Classification," Journal of the American Statistical Association, XLIX (1953), 732-64. Grabill, W. H. "The Fertility of the United States Popula- tion," in Donald J. Bogue, The Population of the Unitoo States. Glencoe: The Free Press, 1959, pp. 288—324. , C. V. Kiser, and P. K. Whelpton. The Fertility of American Women. New YOrk: John Wiley, 1958. Gras, N. S. B. An Introduction to Economic Histopy, New York: Harper, 1922. Grigg, Charles M. "A Proposed Model for Measuring the Ecological Process of Dominance," Social Forces, XXXVI, No. 1 (December, 1957), 128—31. , and Rupert Vance. "Regionalism and Ecology: A Synthesis?" Florida State University Research Roporpg in Social Science, III, No. 2 (August, 1960), l—ll. Gutman, Robert E. "Comment on Kiser's Paper," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 113-116. "In Defense of Population Theory," American Sociological Review, XXV (June, 1960), 325-33. , and Irving Bender. "Some Sources of Variation in Family Size of College Graduates," Milbank Memorial Fund gparterlyj XXXV (July, 1957), 287-301. Hagood, Margaret J., and Daniel 0. Price. Statistics for Sociologists. Rev. ed. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1952. 365 Hajnal, John. "The Study of Fertility and Reproduction: A Survey of Thirty Years," in Thirty Years of Research in Human Fertility: Retrospect and Prospect. New York: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1959, pp. 11-37. Hamilton, C. Horace. "Population Pressure and Other Factors Affecting Net Rural-Urban Migration," Social Forces, XXX, No. 2 (December, 1951), 209—15. Hashmi, Sultan S. "Trends and Factors in Urban Fertility Differences in the United States.“ Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of Chicago, 1962. "Factors in Urban Fertility Differences in the United States," in Ernest W. Burgess and Donald J. Bogue, Contributions to Urban Sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964, pp. 42—58. Hathaway, Dale, J. Allan Beegle, and Keith Bryant, Rural America, Census Monograph in press. Hatt, P. K., N. L. Farr, and E. Weinstein. "Types of Population Balance," American Sociological Review, XX (February, 1950), 14-21. Hauser, Philip M. "Present Status and Prospects of Research in Population," American Sociological Review, XIII (August, 1948), 371-82. "On Design for Experiment and Research in Fertility Control,‘I in C. V. Kiser, Research in Family_ Plannipg. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 463-74. , and Otis Dudley Duncan. The Study_of Population. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959. Hawley, Amos. Human Ecology. New YOrk: Ronald Press, 1950. Hiller, E. T. "Extension' of Urban Characteristics into Rural Areas," Rural Sociology;§QL(September¢{1941),; 3242—57 0'. I V :5, . Hillery, George, Jr. "Toward a Conceptualization of Demography," Social Forces, XXXVII (October, 1958), 45-51. Hughes, Rufus B., Jr. "Human Fertility Differentials: The Influence of Industrial-Urban Development on Birth Rates," Population Review, III (July, 1959), 58—69. 366 Hutchhmmm” Edward P. "Comment on Ryder's Paper," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 131-33. Jaffe, A. J. "Urbanization and Fertility," American Journal of Sociology, XLVIII (July, 1942), 48—60. Jonassen, Christian. "Functional Unities in 88 Community Systems," American Sociological Review, XXVI (June, 1961), 399-407. Jones, Lewis. "The Hinterland Reconsidered," American Sociological Review, XX (February, 1955), 388-98. Kiser, Clyde V. Group Differences in Urban Fertility. Baltimore: Williams and Wilkins, 1942. . "Changes in Fertility by Socio—Economic Status during 1940-50," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXIII (October, 1955), 393-429. "Fertility Trends and Differentials in the United States," Journal of the American Statistical Association, XLVII (March, 1956), 162-83. "Methodological Lessons of the Indianapolis Fertility Study," Eugenics Quarterly, III (September, 1956), 152-56. "Differential Fertility in the United States," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demogpaphic and Economic Chapge in Developod Countries. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 77-113. , and P. K. Whelpton. "Fertility Planning and Fertility Rates by Socio—Economic Status," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXVII, No. 2 (April, 1949), 188-244. , and P. K. Whelpton. "Resume of the Indianapolis Study of Social and Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility," Population Studies, VII (1953), 95—110. Kish, Leslie. "Differentiation in Metropolitan Areas," American Sociological Review, XIX (August, 1954), 388-98. Kitagawa, Evelyn M., and P. M. Hauser. "Trends in Differen— tial Fertility and Mortality in a Metropolis--Chicago," in E. Burgess and D. Bogue, Contributions to Urban Sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964, pp. 59-85. 367 Kunz, Phillip R. "The Relation of Income and Fertility," Journal of Marriage and the Family, XXVII (November, 1965), 509-13. Lorimer, Frank. Culture and Human Fertility. New YOrk: International Documents Service, Columbia University Press, 1955. McKenzie, R. D. The Metropolitan Community. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1933. Martin, Walter T. "Ecological Change in Satellite Rural Areas," American Sociological Review, XXII (April, 1957), 178-83. Mayer, Kurt. "Fertility Changes and Population Forecasts in the United States," Social Research, XXVI, No. 3 (Autumn, 1959), 347—66. Merton, Robert K. Social Theory and Social Structure. Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1957. Mishler, Elliot, and Charles Westoff. "A Proposal for Research on Social Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility: Concepts and Hypotheses," in Current Research in Human Fertilipy, New YOrk: Milbank Memorial Fund, 1955. Moore, Wilbert. "Sociology and Demography," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Popplation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959, pp. 832-51. Notestein, Frank W. "Class Differences in Fertility," The Annals, CLXXXVIII (November, 1936), 26-36. . "Population-~The Long View," in T. W. Schultz, Food for the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1945. , and X. Sallume. "The Fertility of Specific Occupation Groups in an Urban Population," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, X (April, 1932), 120-30. Okun, Bernard. Trends in Birth Rates in the United States since 1870. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1958. Pearl, Raymond. The Biology of Population Growth. New York: Knopf, 1925. Quinn, James A. Human Ecology, New York: Prentice-Hall, 1950. 368 Robinson, W. S. "Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Individuals," American Sociological Review, XV (1950), 351-57. Robinson, Warren C. "Urbanization and Fertility: The Non— Western Experience," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XLI, No. 3 (July, 1963), 291-308. Rosenquist, Carl M., and Alvin H. Schafft. "Differential Fertility in Rural Texas," Rural Sociology, XII (March, 1947), 21—26. Ruggles, Richard, and Nancy Ruggles. ”Differential Fertility in the United States Census Data," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Demogpaphic and Economic Change in Developed Countries. wPrinceton: Princeton University Press, 1960, pp. 155-206. Ryder, N. B. "Fertility," in P. Hauser and O. D. Duncan, The Study of Population. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1959, pp. 400—36. Ryder, Norman. "Variability and Convergence in the American Population," Phi Delta Kappgp, XLI (June, 1960), 379-383. Schnore, Leo. ”Social Morphology and Human Ecology," American Journal of Sociology! LXIII (May, 1958), 620-34. . "Social Mobility in Demographic Perspective," American Sociological Review, XXVI, No. 3 (June, 1961), 407-23. . "The Rural-Urban Variable: An Urbanite's Perspective," Rural SociologY. XXXI, No. 2 (June, 1966), 131—43. Selvin, Hanan C. "A Critique of Tests of Significant in Survey Research," American Sociological Review, XXII (October, 1957), 519—27. Snedecor, G. W. Statistical Methods. 5th ed. Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1956. Sorokin, Pitrim A. Social Mobilipy. New York: Harper, 1927. , and C. C. Zimmerman. Principles of Rural-Urban Sociology. New YOrk: Henry Holt, 1929. Stoeckel, John, and J. Allan Beegle. "The Relationship between the Rural-Farm Age Structure and Distance from a Metropolitan Area," Rural Sociology, XXXI, No. 3. (September, 1966), 346-54. 369 Sydenstricker, Edgar S., and Frank W. Notestein. "Differen— tial Fertility According to Social Class," Journal of the American Statistical Association, XXV (March, 1930), 9—32 0 Thompson, Warren S. "Population," American Journal of Sociology; XXXI (May, 1929), 959-75. , and Nelle E. Jackson. "Fertility in Rural Areas in Relation to Their Distance from Cities, 1930," Rural Sociology, V (June, 1940), 143-62. Tisdale, Hope. "The Process of Urbanization," Social Forces, XX (1942), 311—16. United Nations. The Determinants and Consequences of Population Trends. New YOrk: United Nations, Depart- ment of Social Affairs, Population Division, 1953. U. S. Bureau of the Census. U.S. Census of Population: 1960. Number of Inhabitants. United States Summary, Final Report PC (1)-1A. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1961. U. S. Bureau of the Census. U.S. Census of Population: 1960. General Social and Economic Characteristics. United States Summary, Final Report PC(1)-lC. Washing- ton, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1962. U. S. Bureau of the Census. U.S. Census of Population: 1960. Subject Reports. Women by Number of Children Ever Born. Final Report PC(2)-3A. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1964. Vance, Rupert. "Is Theory for Demographers?" Social Forces, XXXI (1952), 9—13. , and Sara Smith. l'Metropolitan Dominance and Integration," in R. B. Vance and N. J. Demerath (eds.), The Urban South. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1954, pp. 114-34. Westoff, C. F. "The Changing Focus of Differential Fertility Research: The Social Mobility Hypothesis," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXXI, No. 1 (January, 1953), 24—38 0 . "Differential Fertility in the United States: 1900 to 1952," American Sociological Review, XIX, No. 5 (October, 1954), 549-61. 370 Westoff, C. F., E. G. Mishler, and E. L. Kelly. "Preferences in Size of Family and Eventual Fertility Twenty Years After," American Journal of Sociology, LXII (March, 1957), 491-97. , R. G. Potter, Jr., P. C. Sagi, and E. G. Mishler. Family Growth in Metropolitan America. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1961. , Robert G. Potter, Jr., and Philip C. Sagi. The Third Child: A Stugy in the Prediction of Fertilipy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963. , P. C. Sagi, and L. E. Kelly. "Fertility Through Twenty Years of Marriage," American Sociological Review, XXIII, No. 5 (October, 1958), 549-56. Whelpton, P. K. "Geographic and Economic Differentials in Fertility," The Annals, CLXXXVIII (November, 1936), 37—55. , and C. V. Kiser. "Social and Psychological Factors Affecting Fertility: I. Differential Fertility among 41,498 Native—White Couples in Indianapolis," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, XXI (July, 1943), 221-80. Williams, Robin M., Jr. "American Society in Transition: Trends and Emerging Development in Social and Cultural Systems," in James H. Copp, Our Changing Rural Society: Perspectives and Trends. Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1964. Woofter, T. J. "Trends in Rural and Urban Fertility Rates," Rural Sociology, XIII (March, 1948), 3-9. Wrong, Dennis. Population. New York: Random House, 1956. APPENDIX A DETAILED RESULTS OF MULTIPLE REGRESSION EQUATIONS 372 Table 49. First—order partial correlation of fertility and employment in agricultural occupations (urbaniza- tion) controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and division, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Fertility and Farm- Fertility and Farm ers & Farm Managers Laborers & Foremen Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and DIVISlonS rY2.1 rY2.1 rY2.1 rY3.1 rY3.1 rY3.1 UNITED STATES .138* .076* -.041* .327* .243* .110* New England -.043 .345* .346* .279* .593* .324 Middle Atlantic .028 .046 -.080 -.008 .104 .161 E. N. Central —.049 -.l78* -.188* -.110* -.069 .167* W. N. Central .045 -.005 -.045 .000 -.001 .237* South Atlantic .130* .125* -.166* .174* .202* .075 E. S. Central —.054 —.029 -.311* —.l73* .133* .091 W. S. Central .092 —.036 -.268* .624* .513* .128* Mountain .286* .235* -.205* .168* .198* -.107 Pacific .340* -.014 —.247* .328* .345* -.041 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Percent of male labor force who are employed as farmers and farm managers. X Percent of male labor force who are employed as farm laborers and foremen. 11" 373 Table 50. First-order partial correlation of fertility and socio—economic status controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divi— sions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Fertility and Fertility and Education Family Income Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and D1V151°n5 rY4.l rY4.1 rY4.1 rY5.1 rY5.1 rY5.1 UNITED STATES -.l91* —.225* -.l69* .063* .088* .119* New England .038 —.353* -.l40 —.l47 —.308* -.198 Middle Atlantic .085 .001 -.017 -.l76* .019 .007 E. N. Central .060 -.178* -.398* .296* -.273* -.248* W. N. Central -.175* -.278* -.404* -.323* -.l76* —.096* South Atlantic —.278* -.385* -.268* -.116* .152* .123* E. S. Central -.l90* -.397* -.247* -.037 -.l70* -.010 W. S. Central -.629* -.564* -.496* .051 -.098* -.289* Mountain -.487* -.4l9* .007 .147 —.286* .053 Pacific -.456* -.595* —.356* -.040 -.095 -.238* *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X Median years of school completed by males and females, age 25 and over. X Median family income in 1959. 5 l 374 Table 51. First-order partial correlation of fertility and wife's alternative opportunities controlling for metropolitan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Fertility and Female Fertility and Personal Income Female Employment Conterminous __ United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and D1V1Sl°ns rY6.1 rY6.1 rY6.1 rY7.l rY7.1 rY7.l UNITED STATES —.231* -.205* -.l45* -.179* —.279* —.l44* New England —.092 —.348* -.265* —.073 —.l93 —.081 Middle Atlantic —.354* -.260* -.112 —.239* —.294* -.037 E. N. Central —.l59* —.195* —.1l3* -.028 -.ll4* .007 W. N. Central —.343* -.112* -.202* -.l65* -.039 -.023 South Atlantic -.295* -.289* -.l79* -.245* -.408* -.224* E. S. Central -.l89* -.211* -.203* -.330* -.528* -.430* W. S. Central -.235* -.148* —.l97* -.l46* -.l97* -.205* Mountain -.372* -.234* -.l7l* —.455* -.391* -.211* Pacific -.378* -.119 .011 -.185 -.087 -.020 *Significantly different from zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. x6 X Percent females, 7 Median female personal income in 1959. age 14 and over, who are employed. 375 Table 52. First-order partial correlation of fertility and demographic age structure controlling for metro- politan dominance for conterminous United States and divisions, by residence: 1960 Correlation of Correlation of Fertility and Fertility and Females, Ages 15—24 Females, Ages 25-34 Conterminous United States Urb RNF RF Urb RNF RF and D1V1Sl°n5 rY8.1 rY8.1 rY8.1 rY9.1 rY9.1 rY9.1 UNITED STATES -.366* -.l28* -.l37* .208* .018* .097* New England -.l45 .280* -.226 .106 -.054 .074 Middle Atlantic -.l61 .045 —.015 .202* —.091 -.052 E. N. Central —.529* -.185* —.272* .189* .066 .025 W. N. Central —.516* —.257* -.l64* .229* .096* .090* South Atlantic -.351* —.097* -.071 .186* -.099* .099* E. S. Central -.454* —.039 -.014 .171* -.103 —.013 W. S. Central -.308* —.052 .049 .346* .137* .034 Mountain —.367* -.115 -.354* .069 -.002 .014 Pacific -.316* -.111 -.210* .259* .048 -.005 *Significantly different from.zero at the .05 level. Y Cumulative fertility ratio. X8 Percent ever-married females, ages 15-44, who are age 15-24. X9 Percent ever—married females, ages 15-44, who are age 25-34. 376 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um omen EOHM quHmMMHo mHquoHMHCmHma ammm.m HoH. HoH. HmH. . . . . .Amxv «mImN mmm mam 0:3 .oolmH mmm .memEmm muH£3 omHHHmEIHm>m mo quoumm «mmo.HHI Nom.l oNH. NHH.NI . . . . .Amxv oNImH mmm mam 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo UCmUHmm Nmm.HI mao.u eaH. mNN.I . . . . . .AHxv emHoHasm mum 0:3 Hanson 2H . .um>o oCm oH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCS mo pCmoumm *mmmemlu ooufiel moo. OMOOI e s e e e e e e e e e e e e e e onv hpcgou How mEooCH HmComumm mHmEmw muHCB CmHomz some.a mmo. Hoo. moo. . . w . . . .Amxv msooaH HHHsmm mquz amHamz emon.ol Hmo.I Hog. OON.NI . .A Xv Hm>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE muHCB ha omumHmEoo HOOCUm mo mums» CMHomE *mHm.aH mmN. maN. eNm.m . . . . . . Amxv amsmnoa cam mnmuoan sums was 0:3 muuom HOQmH mHmE mpHCB mo “Cmoumm mmo.: OHo.I NHm. moH.I . . . . . . . Nx mummMCmE Eumm oCm mnmfiumm new 033 mUCOM HOQMH mHmE mpHCB mo quUHmm *MNN.HHI HmN.I mmm. Hoo.0HI . . . . . . . . .AHxV mommaHsoe amuHHoaoupmz amoH.mN .... Hmo.mOH Noo.oooN . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump quumCOU mmsHm> u mquHo COHHMH>mQ mquHonmmoo mmHQMHum> quoCmmmoCH ompCmEoo IHmmeOU osmoCmum COHmmmHmmm mpmm HmHuHmm ammm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHMCHEHmqu mHmHnHCS mo quHonmmoo vNOOMMN s s e s e e e s s e s e e e s e s e e 0 e e s mumgflpmm MO .HOHHm Unggmpm *Hmme e e e e e e e e e e e e s e s e e e s e pamHUHmmmOU COHuMHmHHOU mam-MUHSE IHEHmpCoollhuCCOU mo whom Cones How Hem CCOQ um>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHmCH muouomm mo mHmmHmCm esp mo muHCmmm .aaumH mam oomH “mmumum ompHCD mCOC .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m ooo.H .mm THQMB 377 .Hm>mH mo. may we OHoN Eoum “CmumwwHo mHquUHMHCmHms «omm.N mao. NNH. Nom. . . . .ono emImN mom mum 0:3 .aeumH mom .mmHmEmm wuHC3 omHuHmEIHm>m mo HCmoumm *NmH.oHI NHH.u HNH. NNN.H- . . . .Amxo vNumH mom mum 0:3 .eaumH mom .mmHmEmm muHCB omHunmEIHm>m mo quoemm eoNo.oHu oNN.: HNH. mmN.Hu . . . . .AHxv omHoHosm mum 0:3 Hanson aH .Hm>o oCm oH 0mm .memEmm muHCB mo quonm mONeH' @NOe' moo. 0000' e e e s e e s s s e e e e e AQXV hpcsoo Com mEOOCH HMCOmumm mHmEmm muHCS CMHomz emoa.HH eNN. Hoo. moo. . . . . . Amxo msouaH HHHsmH maHaz cmHomz sSmN.HHI oON.I mmo. ooo.¢l .onv Hm>o oCm mN wmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE muHCB >9 omumHmEOU Hoonom mo meme» CMHomZ *HHH.NH oNN. NoH. oom.H . . . . . Amxo aoamHOH one mumCOQmH same mum 0:3 mouom Hoan mHmE muHCB mo quonm mHm.I mHo.I mHH. Hmo.l . . . . . ANxv mummmCmE Eumm oCm mHmEHmm mum 0:3 monom HOQmH mHmE muHCB mo quoumm imam.oH- «Hm.u moo. mHo.aHu . . . . . . . AHxv mocmcHsoo cmpHHooonumz aHOH.H¢ .... ¢MH.oS mmH.oMHm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Eumu quumCOU mmCHm> u mquHo COHHMH>mo mquHonmmou mmHQMHam> quoCmmmoCH omusmaoo IHmmmoo osmoCmum COHmmmHmmm seem HMHuumm sNHN. . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHMCHEHmqu mHmHuHCE mo quHUHmmeU mom.moN . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . msmEHumm mo nouam osmoCmum *HNm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . “CmHUHmmmoo COHHMHmHHOU mHmHuHCE IlmuCCOU mo sumo EnmmCOCIHmCCC Com Hem CHOQ Hm>m CmHoHHCo mo anECC mCHUCmCHmCH muouomm mo memHMCm may mo muHCmmm .aaumH mom ommH "mmumum omuHCD mCOCHEHmuCoo .mmHmEmw muHCB omHHHmEICm>m ooo.H .am mHnme 378 .Hm>mH mo. one on ones Scum pCmHmHMHo mHquonHCmHma eNoH.m ooo. eNH. amm. . . . .ono amumN 0am 0am 0:3 .eean 0mm .mmHmEmm muH£3 omHHHmEIHm>m mo quonm emom.on ooH.I HoH. oom.Hu . . . .Amxo eNumH mom mam 0:3 .aean 00: .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m m0 quoumm *HmH.mI Noo.: moH. HHo.u . . . . AHxV 00H0H020 0:: 0:3 Hacsoo :H .Hm>o oCm oH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quonmm *mmmem| HfiOe| moo. NNOOI s e e s e e s e e e s e e e wav “fiasco now mEOUCH HMComHmm mHmEmw muHCB CMHomz *mmH.OH mNN. Hoo. mHo. . . . . . Amxv mEOUCH SHHEmH muHC3 CMHomz ammH.NHI mmN.I NHm. mHm.HI .onv Cm>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE muHCB an omumHmEoo Hoonom m0 mammh CMHomZ emoo.H omH. ooH. meH. . . . . . Amxo amsmnom ocm mumuoan Esme was 0:3 monom COQmH mHmE muHCB mo quuumm aoom.N| Hmo.l omo. HmH.I . . . . . ANXV mummmCmE Snow oCm mumfiumm was 0:3 monom HOQMH mHmE mpHCB Ho quonm *me.HHI omN.I H¢N.H oom.oHI . . . . . . . AHxV mUCMCHEoo CmuHHomouumz aNmo.mo .... mmo.mH Hmo.mHmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump quumCoo mmsHm> u mquHo CoHumH>mQ mquHonmmoo mmHQmHum> quoCmmmoCH omquEOU IHmmmoo osmoCmem Conmmummm mumm HmHuHmm somH. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHMCHEamqu mHmHuHCE mo quHUHmmeU omm.mmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . mumEHumm mo nonum osmoCmum *50fie e e e e e e s e e e e e e e e e s e pamfloflwmmou COHmefimHHOU mHmnflgflsz IlhuCCoo mo puma EHmHIHmuCH Cow .ooImH mmm Com CHOQ Hm>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHmCH weepomm mo mHmaHMCm one mo mpHCmmm .mm mHQmB oomH "mmumum omuHCD mCOCHEHmuCOU .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m ooo.H 379 .Hm>mH mo. 0:: 0m 000a gone 0:mu0mmH0 HHuamoHHHcon* OHm.I mmo.: mmm. mNo.I . . . Amxv omImN mmm one 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quUHmm *mHo.NI ooN.: oao. mmH.Hu . . . onv aNImH 00: 0am 0:3 .aaumH 00: .mmHmEMm muHCS omHHHmEIHm>m mo pCmonm mHo.u ooo.: mNH. NHo.n . . . . A xv o0H0H0a0 0:: 0:3 Nucsoo 0H .Hm>o oCm VH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quUHmm Nmmol mfiool HNO. m00.l . o 0 0 o . o o o o o o o . AONV hfiCDOU How mEOUCm HmCOmHmm mHmEmm muHCB CMHomE *eHN.NI mea.u moo. oHo.u . . . . . A xv msouaH HHHsma 00H:3 :mHomz NHN. Hmo. mem.H «om. .Aexo 0030 cam mN 00m .mmHmsme ocm mmHms muHC3 >9 omumHmEoo HOOCUm mo meme» CMHomS eaoo.m on. mNN.m emo.HH . . . . . Amxo :msmnoa oam mnmnoan sumo mum 0:3 wUHOm HOQMH mHmE muHCB mo pCmUHmm :Heo.Nu oNa.: Noo.N Hem.HI . . . . . ANxo mnmomama same on: mumsumm was 0:3 monom HOQmH mHmE muHCB mo HCmUHmm moH.HI mNN.: HoH.m ome.en . . . . . . . AHxv mocmaHsoo :muHHooouumz emHN.N .... mom.mooH mma.mmHm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . sum» panamaoo mmDHm> u mquHo COHHMH>mQ mquHUmemOU mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omusmfioo IHmmmOU osmoCmum COHmmmummm mumm HMHuumm *mmve e e e s e e e e s e e e e e e s e e e COHumCHEHmHmQ mnfimflplfigz HO chmfloflwmmoo owmshNH e e s e s e e e s e e e e e e e e e e s e s e s e wpmgflgmm MO “OH-HM GHMUfiHmum *5500 s e s e e e s s e s e e s s e e e s e e s s “cmfloflmmmou GOHHMHthOU mflmflulfisz BmZIIXHCsoo mo puma Conn: now .oolmH mmm Hem CCOQ Hm>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHmCH muonomm mo mHmmHMCm mCu mo muHCmmm .om mHQmB ommH uConH>Ho oConCm .mmHmEmm mHHCB UmHHHmEIHm>m ooo.H 380 .Hm>mH mo. esp um oumu Eouw quumHMHo mHquonHCmHma mmo.l mmo.: Hmm. NmN.I . . . Amxv omImN mmm mum 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEICm>m Ho quonm mom.u eao.u oem. omH.u . . . Amxv aNImH 0a: 00m 0:3 .aeamH 00m .mmHmEmm muHCS omHuumEIum>m mo quonmm aao.H emH. mos. mHa. . . . . .Aon o0H0Hosm mam 0:3 Haasoo :H .Hm>o oCm vH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo UCmUHmm *ovhenfi' Nmmel mHOO mNo.-I e s e e s e e e e e e e s e onv %“GSOU How mEooCH HmCOmumm mHmEmm muHCB CMHomz *Hom.mu Nma.u woo. mHo.u . . . . . Amxo msoocH HHHsma 00H:3 :mHomz Hoo.HI mmo.l mmm.H Hmm.HI .onv nm>o oCm mN mmm .memem oCm mmHmE muHCB an omumHmEoo HOOCUm mo mums» CMHowS «mHm.m mom. Nmm. mNm.N . . . . . Amxv CmEmHom oCm mumHOQwH Snow mum 0C3 moaom Hoan mHmE muHC3 mo quonm Hmm. mmo. Nom.H ONm. . . . . . ANXV mummmCmE Snow oCm mumfiamm mum 0:3 mUCOM COQMH mHmE muHCB mo quuumm omo.: oNH.I oeH.N moH.NI . . . . . . . .Aon 00cmaHsoo :muHHoaouumz amom.N .... oNH.mmmH Nmo.ooom . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump qunmCOU mmCHm> u mquHu COHHMH>mo mquHonmmoo mmHQmHum> quoCmmmoCH omusmsoo IHmmmou osmoCmum ConmmHmmm mpmm HmHuumm *HMH. . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHMCHECmqu mHmHuHCz mo quHonmmoo mMOCGm O O O 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O I mpmglcflpmm MO HOHHm UHmvgmpm *mmms e s s e s e e e e s e e e e e “cm-WUHHmmOU COflpMI—UmHHOU mHmfluHsz IlmuCCoo mo puma EHmmCOCIHmHCH now use CCOQ nm>m CmHoHHno mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHwCH muowomm mo mHmeMCm one mo muHCmmm .aaan 0a: ommH uCOHmH>Ho CCMHmCm 3oz .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>w ooo.H .mm mHQmB 381 .Hm>mH mo. are no omen Scum quummmHo mHquoHMHCmHms mNH.HI HMH.I mom. omo.: . . . .Amxv «MImN mmo mum 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm wuHsz owHHHmEIHm>m mo quonm mma.Hu ooH.I Noo. oNe.Hu . . . .Amxo eNan mom 00: 0:3 .aeumH 0mm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quonmm eeN.H mom. NHH.H HNH.N . . . . .Aon omsoHosm 0:0 0:3 Huasoo :H .Hm>o oCm oH mm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quoumm *NmmoHl hwvol @mOo mOHoI o o o o o o o o o o o o o o Amxv WUCSOU Mom mEooCH HMCOmHmm meEmm muHCB CMHomz somH.Nn Nmm.u mHo. oao.u . w . . . Amxo msooaH HHHsmH 00H:3 :mHooz NOH. mHo. Hmm.m Hmm. .A xv Hm>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE muHCB an omumeEoo Hoosom mo mums» CmHomz omm.H mNN. mom. momN.H Amxv CmEmHoH oCm mHmHOQMH Enmm mum 0:3 mouom HOQMH mHmE wuHCB mo quUHmm ooh. HNH. NHm. NNo. . . . . . ANXV mummmCmE Eumm oCm mHmEHmm mum 0:3 monom HOQMH mHmE muHCB mo quoumm NHH.: Nmo.- Noe.m ooa.Hu . . . . . . . Aon 00cquaoo :muHHooonumz *Nmm.m .... mmm.0HHH oom.NNmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Esme pCmmeOU mmCHm> u mquHo COHHMH>mo mHCmHUHmmmou mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omnnmfioo IHmmmoo osmoCmum ConmmHmmm mumm HmHuumm «mmo. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHumCHEHmCmo mHmHuHCE mo quHUHmmmoo hmOemmN e s e e o e e e o e e s s e e e e e e s e mumgflumm mo HOHHM UHqumpm *wN-Oe e e e e e e s e e e e e e e e e e e “GmHUHmmmOU COHNMHmHHOO mI—HQHUHSE ommH ”ConH>Ho oCmHmCm 3oz IlmuCCoo mo puma EummleHCH How .ooImH mmm .mmHmEmm mpHCB omHHHmalum>m ooo.H Hem Cuon Hm>m CmHoHHCo mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHmCH mnouomm mo mHthow mnu mo muHCmmm .mm mHQmB 382 .Hm>mH mo. may no oumn Eoum quHCMMHo NHHCMUHMHCmHms mNm. omo. moo. omo. . . . .Amxv vamN mmm mum 0:3 .ooImH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIum>m mo quoumm *Hoo.HI omH.u mos. ooH.u . . . .Amxo eNImH mom mum 0:3 .aaImH 0am .mmHmEmm muHCB omHuumEIHm>m mo quUumm Nom. ooo. Hoe. oNN. . . . . .Aon omsoHosm mum 0:3 Huasoo :H .nm>o oCm oH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quonm *amH.mu ooa.u HHo. aeo.u . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .ono N::000 How mEOUCH HMCOmHmQ meEmm muHCB CMHomZ ammo.MI mmN.: moo. Hmo.l . . . . . .Amxo mEOUCH XHHEmm muHCB CmHomz mHN. oHo. mmm.H mmN. .onv Hm>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE mpHCS >9 omumHmEoo Hoonom mo meme» CMHomz mom.- HNo.- NHH.N eao.n . . . . . Amxo casmnoa ocm mnmuoamH 50mm was 0:3 mUHOH COQMH mHmE muHCB mo DCmoumm omH. NHo. mmH.N ooo. . . . . . ANXV mummMCmE Eumm oCm mHmEHmm mum 0C3 mUHOM HOQmH mHmE muHCB mo quUHmm *HmN.mu mHe.u oNo.H HNH.oHI . . . . . . . .Aon 00cm:Hsoo :00HH000u002 aHmo.o .... oNo.mmm NmN.oHNo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Esme quumCOU mmCHm> u mpCmHo CoHumH>mo mquHUHmmmoo mmHQmHum> quoCmmmoCH ompsmaou Imemou UnmoCmpm ConmmHmmm mumm HmHuumm *mHm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CoHumCHEHmqu mHQHuHCZ mo UCmHUHmmmoo NmfieOMH e e e e e s e e o e s e e s e e s e e e e mUMEHumm mo HOHHm ©HMUGM“W *NHO. . 0 0 o . . . o o o o o . o o o o . UCGflUHWMwOU COH#MHOHHOU OHQHHHSZ mHoonIImuCCoo mo puma Cones Cow .ooImH mmm Hem CHOQ Cm>m CmHoHHCo mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHwCH muouowm mo mHmemCm was mo muHCmmm .mm mHQmB ooNH HSEC/Ho 0H0:mH0: .mmHmEmw muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m ooo.H 383 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um omen Scum quummmHo mHquoHMHCmHma eom.u mNo.: omo. HNH.: . . . .ono amImN mew mew 0:3 .aeumH 0mm .mmHmEmw muHCS omHHHmEIHm>m mo quonm oHN.- mNo.: oom. oaH.I . . . .ono «NImH mom on: 0:3 .aaumH 0o: .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quonm wooN.NI mmN.- Ham. mmN.HI . . . . .AHxv omsoHasm 00: 0:3 Huasoo :H .Hm>0 oCm «H mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quUHmm HmHe' NNOOI Mun—”Os MOOOII e s e e e e e o s e e e e s e Amxv ”HQSOU now mEooCH HMComeQ meEmm wuHCB CMHomE Hmo.u oao.u oHo. NHo.I . . . . . .Amxo msooaH HHHsma m0H:3 :mHoms Hmo.H omo. OHm.H moH.H .onv Hm>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE muHCB an omumHmEoo HOOCUm mo memo» CMHomE amHm.H mHN. mmm.H oom.N . . . . . Amxv CmEmHom oCm mHmHOQMH Eumm was 0:3 muuom HOQMH mHmE muHC3 mo pCmonm Nmm.l moo.l mom.N omo.: . . . . . ANxV mummMCmE Snow oCm mumEHmm . was 053 moaom HOQMH mHmE muHCB mo quuamm «mHo.mI on.I ONo.N moo.oHI . . . . . . . .AHXV moCmCHEoo CmpHHomouumz amom.m .... Hmm.NHm omh.mmmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Esme quumCOU mmsHm> u mquHo CoHDMH>mo mquHonmmoo mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omquEOU IHmmmou osmoCmum Conmmammm mumm HMHpHmm *mmm. s e e e s e e o o e s s s s e e GOHHMH‘HHEHmflmg mflmncfl “H52 “0 “cmlfiolfimmmoo mmm. flmlfi O O O 0 O O O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O 0 mflmElofi“mm mo HOHHW Unmwgmum swam. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . o . . . UCOHUHNMOOU H.HO._H...Hm._HOHHOU OHQHUHSE IlmuCCOU mo puma EummCOCICmHCH How .ooImH mmm Hem Cuon um>m CmuoHHCo mo CmQECC mCHUCmCHHCH mnouomm mo mHmmHMCm mCu mo muHCmmm .om mHQme oooH ":0HmH3Ho 0HucmH0< 0Hoon .mmHmEmm GHHCB omHHHmEIHm>m ooo.H —_—=—.———..H F .Hm>mH mo. one on ones Eouw quHmmmHo mHquoHMHCmHma Hmo.HI mmH.I moo. oom.l . . . .Amxv omImN mmm was 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quUHmm HNm.Hu emH.I Nmo. moN.Hu . . . .Amxv eNImH 0mm 000 0:3 .eean 0mm .mmHmEmm muH£3 omHHHmEIHm>m mo quoumm ooo. meH. ooN.H HaH.H . . . . .AHxv omsoHoam 00: 0:3 N:::00 :H .Hm>o oCm oH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB mo quUHmm Ammo-HI- mvNe' omo. vael 0 e e s e e e e e e 0 e e e s AOXV “pcsoo Com mEooCH HmComHmm mHmEmm ouHCB CmHomz mHo.I Noo.- mmo. Hoo.u . w . . . .Amxo msoocH HHHsma 00H:3 :mHomz oem.u NHo.I omN.m omH.NI .A xv 0030 ac: mN 0mm .mmHmsmm ocm mad...a mpHCB an omumHmEoo Hoonom mo mums» CMHomS NQNo.N HmN. ooo. oom.H . . . . . Amxv CmEmuom oCm mumHOQMH Show 4 was 0:3 mouom COQmH mHmE muHCB mo quoamm 8 mNm.HI HoH.I mmo. mmo.: . . . . . ANxv mammMCmE Eamm oCm mumfiumm 3 mam 0:3 monom HOQMH mHmE muHCB Ho quunmm sooh.ol HH¢.I mNo.m mmm.mNI . . . . . . . .AHXV mUCmCHEoo CmuHHomouumz ammH.m .... omH.omo mmo.mmHm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Esme quumCoo mmCHm> u mquHo mCOHumH>mo mquHonmmoo mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omusosoo IHmmmoo osmoCmum COHmmmHmmm mumm HmHuHmm *0mm. 0 e e o e s e o e e s e e s e e e COHflvMCHEHmme mHQHquz MO “cmfloflmwmoo ommOmom O O 0 O O O O O O O O O O O 0 0 O O D O O O l mflmaflpmm MO .HOHHm UHmwfiHmpm *mhve e e e e e s e e e e e e s e s e e e e e “GmHUHmmmOU COHpmHmHHOU mHmeHsz ommH uCOHmH>Ho UHquHu< mHoon Ilmquoo No news EnmmleuCH now .ooImH mmm .mmHmEmm mnHCB omHuumEInm>m ooo.H Hem CHOQ Hm>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHwCH muouumw mo mHmmHMCm ens mo muHCmmm .Ho mHQMB 385 .Hm>wH mo. one no omen EOHH quHmMMHo XHHCMUHMHCmHms «om. Mao. mNm. HHm. . . . . .ono emImN mew mew 0:3 .aean 00m .mmHmEmm muHCB omHuHmEIHm>m mo quUHmm aHoH.mI OHo.I HmN. Nmm.NI . . . . .Amxv oNImH mmm one 0:3 .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHuHmEIHm>m mo quonmm woe. oNo. mom. oeH. . . . . . .Aon omsoHosm 0:: 0:3 Haasoo :H .um>o oCm vH mm .mmHmew wuHCB mo quUHmm *mmOeMI mmIfie| qHOe NfiOel e s s e e e e o e e s s e e e e Amxv >HQDOU Com mEooCH HMComem mHmEmm muHCB CMHomE aomm.o OON. moo. mHo. . . . . . . .Amxv mEooCH XHHEmm muHCS CMHomz amom.m NoH. mNH.H mNo.m . .onv um>o oCm mN mmm .mmHmEmm oCm mmHmE mHHCS an omumHmEoo Hoocom mo mums» CmHomE NHH.H: mmo.- omm.H mNH.H- . . . . . . Amxo :mamuom oam m0000:MH same was 0:3 mouom COQMH mHmE muHCB mo quoumm mom.l oNo.I mHm.H mom.l . . . . . . ANxv mammMCmE Snow oCm mumaumm mum 0C3 muaom HOQmH mHmE wuHCB Ho quUumm *emo.o- ooN.- HNo.H HNo.oH- . . . . . . . . .Aon 00:m:Hsoo :muHHooosumz *NmN.N .... mNm.HOH mmo.ommH . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump quumCOU mmCHm> u mquHo COHumH>mQ mquHonmmoo mmHQmHnm> quoCmmmoCH omquEoo IHmmmou osmoCmum Conmmummm mumm HMHuumm *OHo. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHMCHEumqu mHmHuHCE mo quHUmemOU mmOOth 0 0 O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O O I O O O O mumgflumm MO .HOHHm GHMGGmum *Oflme s e e e e e e e e e e s e e s e s e s s e “cmfloflmmmoo COHumHmHHOU mHQHpHsz oomH ":0HmH3Ho Hmnuamu :0002 ummmllmpCCOU mo puma Cones How .oolmH mmm .mmHmEmm muHCB omHuHmEIHm>m ooo.H Com CCOQ um>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHwCH mnouumw m0 mHmmHMCm mCu Ho muHCmmm .Nm mHQmB 386 .Hm>wH mo. msu um omen Scum quHmmeo .mHquoHMHCmHmin ova.H moo. oHN. Noe. . . . . .Amxo amImN mom mum 0:3 .aeImH 00m .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHumfilum>m mo quUHmm imam.mu emH.I oHN. Hmm.u . . . . .ono «NImH 00m 00m 0:3 .eaumH mom .mmHmEmm muHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quUHmm HoH.H oHo. mHm. mom. . . . . . .AHxV omHOHmEm was 0:3 muCCoo CH .Hm>o oCm oH mm .mmHmEmm wHHCB mo quUHmm *PNHOMI hmI—Hel MHOe HflOs' e e e e e e e e e e C e s e e s wav mpgsoo mom wEooCH HMComumm mHmEmm muHCB CMHomz *mNm.mI oNN.: eHo. oHo.I . . w . . . .Amxo msooaH HHHsmH 00H:3 :mHomz emoH.mI oHH.I HoN.H oam.mu . .A xv 0030 ea: mN 00: .mme50H 00m mmHma muHCB an omumHmEoo Hoosom mo meme» CMHomE mmN.H mmo. mHm. OHH. Amxv CmEmHOM oCm mumHOQmH Emmm mum 0C3 monom HOQmH mHmE mpHCS mo quonmm amoH.oI mMN.I oom. omN.NI . . . . . . ANxV mummmCmE Eumm on mumfiumm mum 0C3 moHOM HOQmH mHmE muHCB mo quonmm eoHe.oI mmN.: omo.H meH.NHI . . . . . . . . .AHxv 00::cHaoo :muHHoaouumz amHm.NH .... mNm.oom mom.HooH . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . and» pCmumCoo mmCHm> u mquHo COHumH>mQ qumHonmmoo mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omusmaoo IHmmmou UnmoCmum COHmmmammm mumm HMHuHmm stN. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHmeHEnmumo mHmHuHCE mo quHonmmoo “NIH O mmlfi O O O O O O O 0 0 O O O O O O O . O O O O O O muggioflpmm mo MOM-Hm UHMUQmpm aHmm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . pCmHUHmmmoo COHumHmHHOU mHmHuHCE IlmuCCoo Mo puma EHMHCOCIHMHCH How .ooImH wmm Hem CHOQ Hm>m CmHoHHCU mo HmQECC mCHUCmCHmCH muouomm mo mHmmHmCm was mo muHCmmm oomH “COHmH>Ho HmnquU Cuuoz ummm .mmHmEmm manz omHHHmE Hm>m ooo.H .mo UHQMB 387 .Hm>mH mo. mCu um ones 800w quHmHMHo mHquonHCmHma Hom. 0N0. Hmm. moN. . . . .ono emumN 000 000 0:3 .aeumH 000 .mmHmEmm mUHCB omHHHmEIHm>m mo quUHmm 0000.0- mNN.: 000. mom.Nu . . . .ono «NImH 000 000 0:3 .eaan 000 .mmHmEmm muHCB omHuumfilum>m mo pCmoumm 0oma.m moN. Ham. N00.H . . . . .Aon 00H0Hos0 000 0:3 H::300 :H . .Hm>0 oCm oH mm .mmHmEmm 00HC® mo quUHmm 3000.NI 00H.I NNo. ooo.: . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .A xv H0::00 00m mEOUCH HMCOmHmm mHmEmm muHCB CMHomz 00NH.NI ooo.: «No. Noo.- . w . . . .Amxo 0:00:H HHHs00 000:3 :00002 0Nom.ou 0Hm.u 0H0.H Nmo.oHn .A xv 0030 0:0 0N 000 .00H0s00 0:0 00H0: muHflz >9 ompmHmfioo HOOCUm m0 mums» CmHomE 000H.¢ 00H. 000. oem.H . . . . . Amxo :0s0000 0:0 00000:0H :00: mum 033 monow HOQMH mHmE muHCB mo quUHmm ammm.mu omN.u 00H. HHo.: . . . . . ANxv 00000:0s 5000 0:0 0005000 000 0:3 mouom HOQMH mHmE muHCB mo quonm eaNm.mu mmN.: 000.m 00H.0HI . . . . . . . .Aon 00:0:0500 :000H000000s 00H0.NH .... mmH.0oa HH0.mHmo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 500: 0:000:00 mmCHm> u mquHU COHHMH>mQ mquHUHmmmoo mmHQMHHm> quoCmmmoCH omesmfiou IHmmmoo oumoCmum COHmmmHmmm mumm HMHuumm soom. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHDMCHEHmme.mHmHuHCZ mo quHonmmoo mnfimemom e e e e e e e e e e e 0 e e 0 e e 0 e e e e e mymgflumm mo .HOHaHm UHmcflHmpm *0000 e e s e e e e e s e e e e e e e s e e e “cmnfloflmmmoo COHUMHmHHOU mHmeHsz IlhuCCOU mo 000m EHmMIHmCCH 00m .ooImH 0mm 00m C009 0m>m CwaoHHCo mo HmQECC mCHoCmCHmCH meouomm mo mHmmHMCm 0C0 mo muHCmmm .om mHQme ommH "ConH>Ho HmnquU Cuuoz ummm .mmHmEmm mans omHHHmE um>m ooo.H 388 .H0>0H mo. 03“ #6 OHMN EOHM HQTHQMHHU \wHUGMUHNHCmHmum ooo. Hmo. Hmm. mmN. . . . . .Amxv 0mImN 0mm 000 0:3 .oolmH 0mm .mmHmamm 00HC3 00H00mfil00>m 00 0C000mm 0NN0.0- mo0.- 00N. omm.N- . . . . .ono 0NImH 000 000 0:3 .00ImH 000 .nonamm 00HCB ©0H0005I00>0 00 0C000mm 000H.N omH. 00m. mom. . . . . . .Aon 0000Has0 000 0:3 00:00: :0 .00>0 0C0 0H 0mm .mmHmamm muHCB mo 0C0000m 0Hmm.0u HmN.u mHo. 000.: . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .ono 00:000 000 0800CH H0C000mm 0Hmamm 00HC3 CmHomz 0mmm.0n ooN.: moo. NNo.- . . . . . . Anxo 0:00:H HHHs00 000:3 :00002 :Nmm.HI mmo.I HmH.H mNm.NI . .A0xv 0030 0C0 mN 0mm .mmHmamw 0C0 mmHma 00HCB >9 omumHQEOU Hoosom Mo 0000% CmHomz H00. NNo. o0o.H H00. . . . . . . Amxo :050000 0:0 00000:0H E00 000 053 00000 0030H 0Hma 00HC3 00 0C000mm NHm.I mHo.I mNH. HHN.I . . . . . . ANxv m00m0CmE E000 oCm 000E000 000 0:3 00000 0090H 0H0E 00HCB 00 0C000mm 000m.mn ooN.- on.N NN0.NH- . . . . . . . . .Aon 00:0:0500 :000H0000002 amoN.o .... Nmm.mmo mom.NmN0 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . E000 0C000C00 mmCH0> 0 mquHo C0H00H>0o mnCmHonmeou 00HQ0H00> 0C00C0000CH ompsmaoo IHmmmoo o0moCoum COHmmm0m0m 000m H0H0000 *HNo. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHumCHE0wumo 0HQH0H52 00 quHonmeoo .NNmOQON O O O O O O O O O O O O O C O O O O O O O O I C O mpMEIoflpmm MO HOHHM “Haggmum *mfloe e e e e e e e e e e o e e e s e e s e e s e “cmfloflmmmou COHpmufimHHOU mflmfluHsz ummzllmquoo 00 0000 C090: 000 .oolmH 0mm 000 C009 00>0 C00©HHC0 mo 00085C mCHUCmsHmCH m0ouomm mo mHmmHMCm 0:0 00 muHCmmm .mm 0HQMB oomH "COHmH>Ho H000C00 £0002 .mmHmemm 00HC3 o0H00mEI00>0 ooo.H 389 .H0>0H mo. 090 00 000m 800m 0C00000Ho hHquuHMHCmHms HNN.H 00o. mmN. mmN. . . . . .Amxo 0mumN 000 000 0:3 .00ImH 000 .00H080m 00H93 o0H0008I00>0 mo 0C0000m 0mHH.mI omN.I NoN. mHm.H- . . . . .wav 0Nan 000 000 0:3 .00umH 000 .00H080m 00H93 o0H0008I00>0 mo 0C0000m 0m0.H Noo. ooN. moo. . . . . . . . ASXV 00%0HQE0 000 093 muCCOU CH .00>0 0C0 0H 0m .0090600 00H93 mo 0C0000m mmoefil thel wnfiOe MNOOI e e s e e e e e s e e e e e e s onv hugsoo 000 0EOUCH H0C0000m 0H080m 00H93 C0Ho0z amNo.mu 00H.: HHo. omo.: . . . . . . .Amxo 0:00:H HHHs00 000:3 :00002 :HN0.oI mmN.: mmo.H omm.oI . .onv 00>0 oCm mN 0mm .00H080H oCm 00H08 00H93 >9 U000HQEOU Hoonom 00 0000» C0H©0z oom. omo. 00m. 0Hm. . . . . . . Amxo :0s0000 0:0 00000:0H E00.0 000 093 00000 0090H 0HmE 00H93 00 0C0000m ammm.HI Hmo.l mmN. mm0.I . . . . . . ANxv 000m0Cmfi E000 0C0 0008000 000 093 00000 0090H 0H08 00H93 00 uC0000m 0Hmm.mu 0HH.I H00.N 0NH.mu . . . . . . . . .Aon 00:0:0000 :000H000000z *mHm.HH .... NNH.om0 mmN.omHm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . E000 quumCoo m0CHm> u 00C0H0 C0H00H>0o 00C0H0me000 00H90H00> 0C0oC0m0oCH 00050800 IHmm0OU o0moC00m C0H0000m0m 000m H0H00mm *HOHO e e e s s s e e e s e s e e e O s s GOHuMfiHHEHmUmQ mHQHHng MO “GmHUIoflmmmOU q0m0m¢N O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O C I O O O mpmpHHuflmm MO HOHHm GHmwcmpm *hm¢e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e s e e “cmnflU-flwmmou HMO-WNWMHmHHOU GHQHpHSE oomH "C0H0H>Ho H000C0U 99002 0003 IlhuCCOO 00 00mm E000C0CIH00C0 000 .oolmH 0mm 00m C009 00>0 C00oHHCU 00 009ECC mCH0C0CH0CH 0000000 00 mHmmHmCm 090 00 00HCm0m .mm 0H9ma .00H080w 00H93 o0H00mEI00>0 ooo.H 390 .00>00 mo. 000 00 0000 E000 000000000 00000000000000n 0mm. moo. mom. mmo. . . . . .0000 00:00 000 000 003 .00100 000 .0000E00 00003 000000E|00>0 00 0000000 0000.0- 000.: 0mm. 000.0: . . . . .0000 0Nnm0 000 000 on; .00um0 000 ‘0000000 00003 000000EI00>0 00 0000000 000.0 moo. 00m. N00. . . . . . .0000 00000000 000 on; 000000 :0 .00>o 000 00 00 .0000E00 00003 00 0000000 *HOMOM' omHol mHOo mm00| o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o onv ”UGSOU 000 0E000A 00000000 000E00 00003 000002 000.0- 000.- 000. omo.: . . w . . . .0000 000000 000000 00003 000000 0000.001 00m.l 000.0 000.00: . .A xv 00>0 000 mm 000 .0000E00 000 0000E 00003 00 000000E00 000000 00 00000 000002 0m00.0 00m. 000. 000.0 . . . . . . Amxv 0000000 000 00000000 0000 000 003 00000 00000 000E 00003 00 0000000 00m.| mmo.l 000. 000.: . . . . . . Amxv 0000000E E000 000 000E000 000 003 00000 00000 000E 00003 00 0000000 0m0m.mu 000.: mm0.m 000.00: . . . . . . . . .0000 0000:0000 000000000002 00m0.00 .... 00m.mmm m00.m000 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . E000 00000000 00000> 0 000000 000000>00 000000000000 00000000> 00000000000 00000E00 I000000 00000000 0000000000 0000 0000000 *mmm. . o o o . . o . o o . . . o o o . o o . COHHMCHEHQfiGQ mHQH#H52 MO UCGHUHMMGOU “wooflom o o o o o o o o o 0 o o o o o o I o o o o o O o o o mumgflumm MO HOHHm UHmwcmum 0‘5me 0 o o 0 o o 0 o o o o o o o o O o I o I o O O UHH®HHUUHMH$OU QOHUMHmHHOU ml—Hmflpnfigz 0000 "00000>00 0000000 00002 0003 1:000:00 00 0000 E000I00000 000 .001m0 000 .0000E00 00003 000000EI00>0 000.0 000 0000 00>0 00000000 00 000E00 00000000000 0000000 00 00000000 000 00 0000000 .00 00008 391 .Hm>ma mo. map um OHmN Eonm ucmanMflU haucmoflwflcmflm« *Hmm.m moa. Hmm. 0mm. . . . .Amxv «mumm mom mHm 0:3 ~¢¢nma mom .mmHmEmm mufl£3 UmHuHmEIHm>m m0 Humoumm *mmo.hu mNm.- mma. mom.au . . . .Amxv «Numa mam mum 0:3 .wvuma mmm .mmHmEmm muHQB cwHHHmEIHm>m mo ucmuumm *mo>.al moa.l mma. mam.| . . . . .Anxv wmonmEm mum 0:3 mucsoo CH ~uw>o 6cm @H mm .mmamamm mufln3 mo unmoumm *hamom' mmnfio' ooo. PHOOI o o O o o o o o o o o o o O o wav ”HGSOU How mEooca HMCOmumm mHmEmm muHSB amflvmz *mm¢.¢u ooN.: woo. mao.u . . . . . .Amxv maoocfl mafiamm muflnz cmflcmz «mo¢.hl Ham.l con. mma.ml .Afixv um>0 cam mm mom ~mmHmEmm cam memE muHSB an Umumamaoo Hoonum mo mummh mafiwmz mmo.a mwo. an». mmm. . . . . . Amxv cwEmnom mum mumuonma Eumm mum 0:3 mouom Henna mama wuflnz mo unmoumm oom.a «we. 0mm. ¢MH.H . . . . . Amxv mummmnma Eumm cam mumsumm mum 0:3 muuom Honma mHmE muHLB mo unmoumm *omn.au Noa.u noo.a www.mu . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcHEOw cmuflaomouumz *hv©.m .... mah.mon nmm.hoov . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump ucmumcou mmsam> u mucmflo COHuMH>mQ mucmHUHmmmoo mmanmflnm> ucmwcmmmccH Umusmfiou Iflmmmou Unmwcmum coflmmmumwm mumm Hmflunmm *hmm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . coflumcflaumumo mamfluasz mo ucmHUHmmmou “whommnfi o o o o o O o o o o o 0 o o o o O o o 0 mumEflumm mo .HOHHm @Hmmvcmum *omoo o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o UCQHUH—uwmmoo COHHMHmHHOU mHm-flpnfigz coma “conH>HU oaucmaufi Susomllmucsoo mo puma cmnus How .fiwlma mom ~mmam8mw mpflnz Umfluumfilum>m ooo.H Hmm GHOQ Hm>m cmuwaflno mo Hmnfisc mcflocmdamcfl muouoww mo mflmhamcm mnu mo muasmmm .mm magma 392 11354. . . .Hm>ma mo. ms“ um oumN Scum ucmeMMHG hauchflMHcmHm¥ woa.u woo.u mom. mmo.- . . . . .Amxv «mumm mom mum 0:3 .kuma mom .memEmw mufl£3 Umfluumfilum>m mo ucmuuwm ¥mmm.ou H¢N.u Hum. mo>.Hu . . . . .Amxv wmumfl mom mum 0:3 ~¢¢nmfl mom ~mmamamm muHLB Umfluumfilum>m m0 unmoumm ¥mm>.ml mam.| mNN. Hmm.HI . . . . . .Anxv UmmoHQEm mum 0:3 mundoo CH .um>o cam va mm .mmHmEmm muflLB mo unmoumm mNo.-HI omOol 0H0. OHOo-I o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o onv huasou How mEouca anaemmmm wamfimm muflnz cmflwmz mmN. mac. ooo. moo. . . w . . . .Amxv macoafl maflamm ouflzz amflwmz *oom.ml nmm.l com. www.ml . .A xv Hm>0 Gum mm mmm ~mmHmEmm Ucm mmHmE muH£3 an Umumamfiou Hoonom mo mummm amHUmz *mqm.~ MHH. ohm. mam. . . . . . . Amxv swamu0m cam mumuonma gum“ mum 0:3 mouom Honma mama mufl£3 mo unmoumm mmo.: moo.l mmN. ©HO.I . . . . . . Amxv mummwzmfi Eumm cam mHmEHmw mum 0:3 wouom Honma mama mufln3 mo pcmoumm *Hmh.ml Ham.- mom.m Hmm.¢au . . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcHEoc cmuflaomouumz ¥mmm.h .... www.mam moo.mmmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Emmy ucmumcou mmsHm> u mucmwo COHMMH>mQ mucmaoflmmmou mmHQMHHm> pcmwcmmmvcH CmudeOU lawmmoo Cumccmum COHmmmummm mumm Hmfluumm *mom. 0 o I o o o o o o o o o o o o o COHgmGHEHGme mufimflpnfisz MO “Gmnfioflmmmou ,mPMO HMN o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o I o o o mgmgflumm MO .HOHHm Cngamum *moo. O O O I O O O O O O O I O O O C O O O “cmlofioloflmwwou QOflpmHmHHOU mHQIoHUHSS luquDOU mo puma Enmmcoclamusu MOM ~v¢ImH mmm Hmm CHOQ Hm>m cmHUHHSU mo umnfidc mafiuzmsamcfl muouomm mo mflmwamcm may mo muHSmmm .mm magma coma "coflmfl>fln oflucmapm nusom .mmHMEmM O‘WHSZ» UmflHHMEImewm 0007—” HUS CHOQ H®>W COHUHHSU MO HwflESC OCHUCQSfiMCH mHOUUQW MO QHWN&GCQ @flu MO MUHDMOE .Qh GHQQE .Hm>ma mo. mnu um oumu Scum ucmeMMflw waucmoHMHcmHm* mNm.H who. 5mm. haw. . . . . .Amxv wmumm mom mum 0:3 .¢¢uma mom .mmHmEmm mnHSB CmHHHmEIHm>m mo ucmonmm «mmm.mn moa.u aqm. Non.| . . . . .Amxv wmuma mmm mum 0:3 ~¢¢nma mom ‘mmamamm mufl£3 Umfluumfilum>m mo unmoumm mao.al ooa.u mwm. Nmm.- . . . . . .Anxv ammoamsm mgm 0:3 mucsoo afl ~Hm>o mam wa mom ~mmHmEmm muHSB mo pcmoumm mN-mol mMOol mHOo 0000' o o o o o 0 0 o o o O o O o o o Amxv mflcsou How mEoocA HMQOmHmm mHmEmm muH£3 amawmz *wmm.a NHH. moo. mac. . . . . . . .Amxv mEooafl maflamm mpflnz madam: *mnn.m| mmN.: mmo.a mom.ml . .A¢XV Hm>o cam mm mmm ~memEmm 0cm mmHmE mgfl£3 >9 wmumamaoo Hoonum mo mummm Gwavmz *mnn.m NNH. mmN. mmn. . . . . . . Amxv swamu0m can mumuonma gumm 3 mum 0:3 mouom Momma mama muwfiB mo ucmuumm 9 «mom.¢l mam.l mva. mon.| . . . . . . Amxv mummmame Eumm Usm mHmEumw 3 mum 033 mouom Honma mama muH£3 mo unmoumm *mmo.ml cam.u Hoh.m www.mau . . . . . . . . .Aaxv moamcHEow amuflaomouumz *Hwh.m .... vmv.anm No¢.mmmm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump ucmumcoo mmsam> u mucmflo coaumfl>mm mucmfloflmwmoo mwanmflum> ucmwcmmmwcH mmusmaoo Iflmmmou Unmwcmum scammmummm mumm HMflpumm *NONI 0 o 0 o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o COflgmgHEHmqu mnfimflunflsz MO pamncfinvnofimmmoo HN®OHmm O O O O O O I O O O O O O O .0 O O O O O O O O O O O mumEI-Humm mo “OH-Hm Ugmwgmpm *m.v¢0 o o o o o 0 o 0 o I o o o o o o o o o O o o o “cmHUHmmwou COHUMHmHHOU mHmflgflsz coma "cowmfl>flw Uflucmaum nusom Ilmgcsoo mo #Hmm EHmMIHMHSH Mom ~vVImH mmm ~mmHmEmm muH£3 Umfluumalum>m ooo.H umm QHOQ Hm>m cmuwaflno mo Hmnfisc mGHUGmSHmQfl muouomw Mo mamhamcm mflu m0 muasmmm .om GHQMB 394 .am>ma mc. mnu um OHmN Eoum pcmummmao maucmoamacmam* moo. omo. mmm. oom. . . . . .onv omumm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mom .mmamamm mua£3 UmaHHmEIHm>m wo ucmuumm *ooo.ou Noo.- mom. ooo.au . . . . .onv omuma mom mum 0:3 .vouma mom .mmamEmm muanz Umauumfilum>m mo uamuumm *ovm.mu oom.u 5mm. wom.au . . . . . .onv om>0aoam mum 0:3 mucsou ca .Hm>o cam wa mmm .mmamamm muasz mo ucmonmm mQMOn—H HHHO 0H0. NNo. o o o O O I o o o I o O o O O o onv mpgsoo How mEooca amQOmumm mamEmm muanz cmaomz oao. woo. moo. ooo. . . w . . . .Amxv maooca maaamm moanz cmaomz *noo.mu ooa.u oma.a ooo.m- . .A xv um>o cam mm mom .mmamEmm ocm mmama mua£3 >9 Umumamaou aoosom mo mummm amaomz oama.mn nma.u oom.a moo.mu . . . . . . Amxo swamuom oam mumuonma ammo mum 0:3 mouom Honma mama mua£3 mo unmommm amm.l mac.l wmm. cam.l . . . . . . Amxv mummmcmfi Eumm ocm mumfinmm mum 0:3 mUHOM Honma mama man3 m0 udmoumm *Noo.au maa.u vmm.m oom.ou . . . . . . . . .Aaxo muomaasoo cmuaaooouumz *mmmom 0000 mmooomm NOhomomN o 0 o o o o 0 o o I o O o o o EHmp “cmpmcoo mmSam> u mucmao coauma>mm mpcmaoammmou mmanaHm> ucmocmmmoca omusmfioo Iammmou oumocmum Goammmummm mumm amapumm *avm. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . coaumcaEHmqu mamauasz mo usmauawmmou Nmmoomafi o o o o O o o o o o o o o o o o o a 0 o mumgflpmm mo .HOHHM Gumccmpw *wme o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o mpCQHUHmmwOU COH“MH$HHOU m-HAWHUHHSZ coma "coama>ao amuucmo zpsom umthlmuasoo mo puma Conn: now .vwlma mmm .mmamEmm muaSB omauumfilum>m ccc.a umm anon Hm>m cmuoaano mo Hmnasc maaUGmSamca muouomm mo mammamcm mnu mo mpasmmm .ah manB .am>ma mc. may pm oumm Eoum ucmumwwao Manamoamaamam* mmo.: omo.: ooo. omo.: . . . . . ono omumm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mmm .mmamEmm mua£3 omauumfilum>m mo unmoumm *m¢¢.¢l mcm.l cmd. mom.al . . . .Amxv ¢m|ma wmm mum 0:3 .fifilma mmm .mmamfimw muanz omauumEInm>m mo ucmonmm *moo.on ooo.: mam. ooa.mu . . . . .ono ommoaoam mum on: mpcsou ca .Hm>o cam va mmm .mmamEmm mua£3 mo unmoumm *Nmmom NmHo HNO. @000 o o o o 0 o o o o o o o o o AQXV >¥CSOU Mom mEOUGA amemem mamamm muanz cmaomz *ooo.an ooo.] ooo. oao.u . w . . . .Amxo maouca maflEmm moans cmaomz *flmm.ml moa.l omo.a mmv.ml .A NV Hw>0 Ucm mm mmm .mmamEmm Una mmamE muaSB >9 omumamaoo aoonom mo mummm :maomz *mho.m ooa. mom. moo.a . . . . . Amxo swamuom ocm mumuonma ammo % mum 0:3 monom Honma mama muanz mo ucmoumm 3 *aoo.mu oma.u moo. oom.an . . . . . Amxv mumomcme Eumo mom mumeumm mum 0:3 monom uonma mama muanz mo ucmuuwm *cam.¢| cam.l onm.¢ mmo.cml . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcaaoo cmuaaomouumz «mom.m .... cmv.¢mm m¢c.mmm¢ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Enmu ucmumcoo mmSam> u mucmao coauma>mm mucmaoammmoo mmanwanm> pcmocmmmoca omusmfioo Iammmoo oumocmum ceammmnmmm mumm amauumm *00m. 0 o o o o o 0 o o o o o o o o o o COHHMQHEHmme mufimflpnfififlz mo “gm-WO-Wmmmou HovI th I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mpmgflpmm MO .HOHnHm wumwcmpm *mmoo o o o a 0 o o o o O o I o o o 0 o o o o “amfloflmmmoo QOHng—HQHHOU mflmflgnfisz coma "coama>ao amuucmu nusom ummm Ilmucsou mo puma Eummcozlamnsu Mom .fifilma mmm ~mmamEmm mpasz omaHHmEIum>m ccc.a Hmm anon Hm>m Cmuoaano mo Hmnfisc mcHUCmsawca muouomm mo mammamcm wan mo muasmmm .mm manme 396 Illm. aria”, .am>ma mo. mop pm oumu scum ucmummmao waocmoamaamamo omo.: aao.u mom. ooo.: . . . .ono omumm mom mum 0:3 .ovuma mom .mmamfimm muaLB omauumfilum>m mo ucmonmm *hmo.ml oma.| mmo. mao.al . . . .A xv fimlma mmm mum 0:3 ~¢¢Ima mmm .mmamEmm mua£3 omaHHmEIHm>m mo unmonmm *mam.ns ooo.: mum. oao.m- . . . . .ono ommoaoEm mom 0:3 apnoea ca .Hw>o ocm wa mmm .mmamfimm mua£3 mo unmoumm womanfi H000 dNOo mmo. o o O o o o o o o o o o o o o onv ”UHHSOU Mom mEooca amcomumm mamfimm muasz cmaomz mmo.l mmc.l cmc. mac.l . . . . . .Amxv mfiooza maaEmm mua£3 Gmaomz *mac.ml vaa.l ¢mv.m amm.¢l .avxv Hm>o cam mm mmm .mmamEmm cam mmamE mpanz >9 omumamaou aoonom mo mumm» cmaomz *ofla.¢ mcm. mmm. mc¢.a . . . . . Amxv cwEmHOM oam mumuonma Eumm mum 0:3 mouom Honma mama muaSB mo unmonmm *omo.on mNm.: ova. Noo.a- . . . . . Amxo mumomama ammo osm mumsumm mum 053 monom Honma mama muazz mo pcmoumm *oo~.~- oaa.n mo¢.m oom.mau . . . . . . . .Aaxo mocmaaaoo cmpaaooouumz *mmo.aa .... mmo.omv ¢¢m.mmmv . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Bump ucmumcoo mmsam> u mucmao coauma>ma wunmaoammmoo mmanmaum> ucmocmmmocH Umusmaou lawnmoo Unmozmum coammmnmmm mumm amaunmm *mmm. o o O o o o o o o o o 0 o o o o o COHHQCHEHmme mHQHUHDz mo pgmflUHMMOOU QOOOHNM O O o o o o o o o o o o o o o o O o o O o o o mpmgflpmm mo .HOaHaHm GHmUfiHmpm *Nmmo o O o o O o o o o o o o o o O o o o o o “Gmflouflmmmou GOHU.MHm«H.HOU mn—Hmufiu-HHHE coma "coama>ao amuucmo nusom pmmmllaucsoo mo puma EHMMIamusu How .¢¢Ima mmw .mmamamm mpanz omauume Hm>m ccc.a umm anon Hm>m cmuoaano mo HmQESG mcaocmSamCa muouumw mo mammamcm may mo muasmmm .mm magma .am>ma mc. may um oumN EOHM ucmummmao maucmoamacmam* *ooo.o ooo. ooo. oqo.a . . . . .ono omumm mom mum 0:3 .oonma mom ~mmamEmm wuana omauumelum>m mo pamonmm *moa.qn noa.n mmN. omo.au . . . . .Amxo omuma mom mum 0:3 .oouma mom .mmamfimm muan3 UmaHHmEIHm>m mo unwonwm mmo. omo. oom. ooN. . . . . . .A xv ommoaoam mum 0:3 oucsoo ca .Hm>o Cam fia mmm .mmamfimm muaLB m0 ucmoumm *HOOINI mOHII mHOI NHVOII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I wav \Agcsoo How mEooca amcomumm mamEmm mua£3 cmaomz *mmm.al moc.l cmc. mmc.l . . . . . . .Amxv mEooca maaEmm muaLB cmaomz *mva.ml aom.l cmm. chc.ml . .avxv Hm>o mam mm mmm .mmamEmm ocm mmamE muaSB >9 omamamfioo aoonom mo mummm cmaomz *moo.o oom. mom. omm.m . . . . . . Amxv swamuom cam mnmuonma sumo mum 0:3 mouom Honma mama mua£3 mo ucmuumm *amm.al ooc.I cmm. mwh.l . . . . . . amxv mummmcma Eumm cam mumEumm 7 mum 0:3 mouom Honma mama mua£3 mo ucmoumm w *ooo.m- ooa.u omo.m owm.man . . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcaaoo cmpaaooonumz *mhm.¢ .... omm.maaa mco.omnv . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Enmu unmumcou mmsam> u mucmao ceauma>mm mucmaoaomwoo mmanmaum> pcmocmmmoca omudmfiou Iammmou oumocmum coammmummm amauumm *OOQI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I COHHMCHEHmU‘mQ mHQHpHSE MO “cmHUHmmmoo mam I NmH I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mpmglofipmm mo “OR-Hm wumvcmpm *NHmI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “Gmfloflwmmou GOflpMHmHHOU mflmflpufisz coma "coama>ao amuucmo nusom ummZIImuCSOU mo puma Conn: How .wvlma mmm .mmamEmm muanz omaHHmEIHm>m ccc.a umm anon Hm>m cmuoaano o0 umnadc mcaucmSamca muouomm mo mammamam mnu mo muasmmm .fin magma 398 .am>ma mc. msu pm oumN EOHM ucmummmao xaucmuamacmamo . . . Amxv fimlmm wmm mum 0:3 .vwlma mmm *wmc.m caa. mom. mob. . .mmamfimm muaSB omanumalum>w mo usmoumm «cmc.m| mca.l mom. mon.l . . . . .Amxv vmlma mmm mum 0:3 .fiwlma mmm .mmamawm mua:3 UmaHHmEIHm>m mo unmoumm oama.mu ooo.: mom. omo.: . . . . . .ono om»0aoam mum 0:3 mucsoo ca .Hm>o mam wa mm .mmamsmm muaSB mo ucmonmm mth' NMOI' ONOI OHOII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I onv wpasoo How mEOUCH amGOmnmm oamEmm mua£3 cmaomz *aoo.mu oma.u oao. omo.: . . . . . . .Amxv macuaa maaamm muanz cmaomz *omm.ol cmm.: mma.a 5cm.m| . .avxv um>o cam mm mmm .mmamamm ocm mmama muanz >9 omumamaoo aoonom mo mummm cmaomz ¥om¢.m wmv. cma. mmo.a . . . . . . A xv :mEmHOM Una mumuonma Sumo mum 0:3 mUHOm Honma mama muass Mo unwonmm *omo.mu ooa.: mom. omo.: . . . . . . Amxv mumomame ammo ocm mumaumm mum 0:3 muuow Honma mama mua£3 mo unmoumm *oom.mu ooo.: mma.o moo.ou . . . . . . . . .Aaxv mommaaeoo cmuaaooouumz omwc.m .... acm.cmo amc.wmom . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sump ucmumcoo mmsam> u mucmao coauma>mo mucmaoammmoo mmanmaum> unmocmmmoca UmusmEOU Iammmou oumocmum coammmummm mumm amauumm *mofiI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I COHHMGHEHmqu mHQHUHHflz mo “cmHU-flmmmov MHQI “MN I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mpmgflumm MO IHOHHm GHMUGmum *mmOI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “cmfloflmwmou conflum-fimHHOU GHQHHHSE coma "Geama>ao amuucwo sysom ummz Ilmucsoo mo puma EummGOCIamusu How .wvlma mmm umm smog um>m cmuoaano mo umnfisc mcaocmSawca muouomm mo mammamcm mnp mo muaSmmm .mm manB .mmamamm muaSB omannmelum>w ccc.a .am>ma mc. may um oumm Eouw ucmnmmmao maucmoamacmam« mmo.: mmo.- «mm. ooa.n . . . . .ono omnmm mom mum 0:3 .ovuma mom .mmamem muanz omauumfilum>m mo ucmuumm omo.- omo.- oom. ooo.- . . . . .onv qmuma mom mum 0:3 .owuma mom .mwamamw mua£3 omaunmfilnm>m mo unmoumm omo.: mmo.: mmo. ooN.: . . . . . .Anxv ommoaQEm mum 0:3 mucsoo ca .um>o cam wa mm .mmamfimm mua£3 mo unmoumm ¢¢mI| NflOII mNOI mNOI' I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I Amxv qusoo How wEOUCH amflOmHmm mamEmm mua£3 Cmaomz *moo.mu aom.n omo. oaa.n . . w . . . .Amxo maooca >aa5mm muaoz :maomz ¥m©¢.wl mo¢.I mmm.H omm.NHI . .A Xv Hm>0 Uflm mN mom .mmHmEmm wflm mmHmE muaSB >9 omumameou aoonom mo mumm» :maomz *mnh.m mam. ooN. ooo. . . . . . . Amxv cmsmuom ocm mumnonma sumo mum 0:3 muuom Honma mama mua£3 mo ucmuumm *cmm.ml oma.l wma. mom.l . . . . . . amxv mummmcme Sumo cum mumaumm % mum 0:3 muuom Honma mama muanz mo unmoumm 3 *oam.mn oma.u ooq.o ooa.oa- . . . . . . . . .Aaxo mucmaaaoo amuaaooonpmz *maa.¢a .... ooo.oam omo.ommn . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . aump ucmumcoo mmSam> u mpcmao coauma>mm mucmaoammmoo mmanmaum> unmocmmmoca omusmfioo lawnmou oumocmum coammmnmmm mumm amauumm *m¢MI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I COflHMCHEHmumD mufimnflunfigz mo ucmflunfiwmmou womIHNm I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mumgflgmm MO HOHHm UHmwcmpm *ommI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “cmHHV-ofimmmov COHpmHmHHOU mHfiHfluHsz coma "coama>ao amnucmu nusom ummzllaucsoo mo puma EHmMIamHSH How .fivlma mmm .mmamEmm mua£3 omauumfilum>m ccc.a Hmm GHOQ Hm>m cmuoaano mo Hmflfidc mcaocmsamca mnouumm mo mammamcm m3» m0 muaSmmm .oo magma 400 .am>ma mo. mop um oumN Eoum ucmummmao aaucmoamacmamo nmm.a who. «on. oao. . . . .onv «mumm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mom .mmamEmm muaSB Umauumalum>m mo ucmoumm *hno.m- oom.s mom. moo.au . . . .onv «muma mom mum 0:3 .owuma mom ~mmamfimm muanz omauumfilum>m mo unmoumm mom.al awa.| mom. mmo.: . . . . .onv ommOaQEm mum 0:3 mucdoo Ca .Hm>o 6cm wa mmm .mmamEmm manB m0 ucmuumm oom.au mma.u oao. omo.: . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .onv apnoea Mom mEooGa amQOmHmm mamfimm mua£3 Gmaomz *omn.a boa. mao. mmo. . . . . . .Amxo maooca maHEmm muaog cmaomz *moo.mu omo.: mNo.m omo.mau .ono um>o ocm mm mom .mmamemw ocm mmama muazz an omumamEou aoosom mo mummm Cmaomz hma. oao. moo. oma. . . . . . Amxv swamH0m ocm mnmgonma ago“ mum 0:3 mUHOm Honma mamE muHSB m0 unmoumm *oha.o mom. omo. moo.o . . . . . Amxo mumomcma sumo oom mumaumm mum 0:3 mouow Honma mamE mwa£3 mo unmoumm *moo.mu oma.u ooo.o oom.nau . . . . . . . .Aaxo mucmaaaoo zmuaaooouumz mom.a .... www.mmom ooo.ooom . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ammo ucmumcoo mmsam> u mucmao coauma>mo mucmaoammmoo mmaflmaum> ucmocmmmocH owusmEOU Iammmoo Cumocmum coammmummm MHmm HMHUHMQ *whmI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I COHumA‘HHEHmw-wma mHQHUHDS MO “cmfloflmwmov HHOIQON I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mgmgflumm mo HOHHm UHmwcmum *NuleI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “amufioflmmmoo COHUMHmHHOU mn—HQHUHSE Camucsozllmucsoo mo pumm cmnus Mom ~Eulma mmm Hmm GHOQ Hm>m cmuoaazu mo umflEdc mzaocmsamca muouomm mo mamwamcm man we muasmmm .om magma oooa ”scama>ao .mmamEmm mua£3 omaunmfilum>m ccc.a 401 .am>ma mc. msu um OHwN Eoum ucmummmao maucmoamacmamI ooo.: Noo.: ooo. mao.u . . . . . . .ono omnmm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mmm .mmamfimm muaSB omaHHmEIum>w mo ucmuumm *noo.mu oma.u mom. ooo.au . . . . . . .onv «muma mom mum 0:3 .oouma 0mm .mmamEmm mua£3 omaHHmEIHm>m mo unmoumm *ooo.mu oam.n mom. mom.au . . . . . .onv omwoaQEm mum 0:3 apnoea ca .Hm>o ocm va mmm ~mmamEmm muanz mo ucmouwm NMOI NOOI MNOI HOOI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I onv %“§OU How mEooca aMCOmHmm mamEmm manB cmaomz *omo.mu aoa.n amo. omo.- . . . . . . .Amxv meooca maaamm moanz amaomz *aom.mu mom.u ooo.a oom.oau . . . . um>o ocm mm mom .mmamamm oqm mmama mua£3 >9 omumamEoo aoonom mo mummm amaomz Noa.n ooo.: amm. ooo.- . . . . . . Amxo swamuom oqm mumuonma Eumm mum 0:3 mouom nonma mamE muaSB mo unmonmm *moo.m aoa. omm. ooa.a . . . . . . Amxo mumomcme aumm oam mumaumm mum osB mouom Honma mama muank mo unmoumm *noa.ou omo.: omo.oa Na~.~¢: . . . . . . . . .Aaxo mucmcaaoo amuaaoooupmz *mom.m .... oao.ooma mom.mmmo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . sump ucmumcoo mmSam> u mucmao aoauma>mo mucmaoawmmoo mmaflmaum> ucmocmmmoca omudmaoo Iammmoo Unmocmum coammmummm mpmm amauumm *flNfiI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I COHU.MCI.HEHmme mHQHuHSS mo “cmflUflmmmOU flmm I mmm I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mumafloumm m0 HOHHm Uhmncmum *n—HmoI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “gmHUHmmeU QOHum-fimHHOU mn—HfimfluHsz coma "coama>ao Camucsoz Ilwuasoo mo puma EumchCIamnsn How .vvlma mmm .mmamamm mua£3 omauumfilum>o cccoa “mm anon Hm>m cmuoaano m0 Hmnfidc mQaUCmSamca muouomm mo mamwamcm mflu mo muaSmmm .mm magma 402 .am>ma mc. mzu um OHmN EOHM ucmumwmao MaucmoamacmamI ooo.: ooo.: moo. aoa.u . . . . . .Amxo omumm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mmm .mmamEmm mua£3 omaHHmEIHm>m mo ucmuumm *nam.mu ooo.- ohm. Noo.m- . . . . . .onv omuma mom mum 0:3 .oouma mmm .mmamEmw muanz omauumfilnm>m mo udmoumm oom.au oma.u mmo. ooa.au . . . . .Anxo ommoaoEm mum 0:3 mucsoo ca .um>o ocm «a mmm .mmamamm muanz mo ucmunmm mQNIHI mOHII mMOI w¢OIII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I Amxv hugoo How wEooca amCOmumm mamem muaSB Gmaomz «ooo.m mma. moo. ooo. . . . . . .Amxv maouca maHEmm moans qmaomz oma.a ooo. omo.m vam.m onv um>o ocm mm mom .mmamamm ocm mmame mua£3 an omumamaoo aoonom mo mummm :maomz hoo.u mmo.: mom. ooa.u . . . . . Amxo swamuom ocm mumuonma Sumo mum 0£3 muuom Honma mama mua£3 mo unmoumm *omo.¢n ooo.- 5mm. mmo.: . . . . . Amxv mumomsma.aumw ocm mumsumm mum 0:3 muuom Honma mama muanz m0 unwoumm oom.an ooa.u mmo.ma oom.¢mn . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcaaoo cmuaaooouumz OMMI IIII OhmImbmfl HNOINmm I I I I I I I I I I I I I I EHmp ucmumgoo mmsam> u mucmao GOauma>mQ mucmauawmmou mmaflmaum> unmocmmmoca omusmsoo Iammmou Unmocmum coammmummm mumm amaunmm Imom. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . COHHmGaEHmuma mamauasz mo unmaoammmoo omNINOq I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mpmgflumm mo .HOHRm wumccmym *mHmI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I pamfloflmmmoo cOHuwHGHHOU mn—HQHUHSZ Ilmuqsoo mo puma EamonamHSH “Ow .wvlma mmm oooa "conH>ao composes .mmamamm mua£3 omauumalum>m ccc.a Hmm cuon Hm>m cmuoaano mo HmQESQ mcaUGmSaMCa muouomm mo mammamcm ms» mo muasmmm .om magma 403 ;Ja4, .am>ma mc. m99 um OHmN Eonm ucwummmao >aucmoamacmam¥ woo. woo. woo. omo. . . . .ono omumm mom mum 0:3 .oonma mom .mwamEmw mpanz omaHHmEIum>m mo udmonmm *Nao.mu ooo.- oom. oom.au . . . .ono omuma mom mum on: .oquma mom .mmamfimw mua93 omaHHmEIHm>m mo unmonmm *ohh.m mom. ooo. oom.a . . . . .Anxv ommoaoam mum 0:3 mpasoo ca .Hm>o ocm wa mmm .mmamfimm m9a93 mo ucmuumm *fiHNImI- Hmel GOOI omOIl I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I onv hygou How QEOUGH amQOmumm mawEmm mpasz cmaomz mmo.- ooo.- oao. aoo.- . . . . . .Anxv mEoooa maaamm moanz cmaomz *omo.¢l mom.u ohm.m oom.aau .onv um>o ocm mm mom .mmamamm ocm mmame muanz >9 Umumamfioo aoo9om m0 mumm> cmaomz omo.- ooo.: ooo. omo.- . . . . . Amxo cmamg0m ocm mumuonma sumo mum 093 mouom Ho9ma mama wua93 mo ucmuumm *aoo.¢ aom. omo. oom.m . . . . . Amxo mumomcme aumm ocm mumsumw mum 093 mouom 909ma mama mua93 mo ucwoumm *oom.¢n ooo.: omo.a oom.ou . . . . . . . .Aaxv mocmcaaoo cmuaaooouumz *oom.m .... mmm.mooa mmo.oomm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ammo ucmumcoo modam> u mucmao ceauma>mo mucmaoammmou mma9maum> ucmocmmmoca omusmEoo Iammmoo Unmocmum coammmummm mumm amauumm *FNQI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I gOHpmsflaumme mHm-Wplfisz m0 “cmfloflmmmoo mquflflH I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mumgflpmm MO HOHHM chmmgmpm *thI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I pgmfloflmmmoo GOHU‘MHmHHOU mnfimlofl“nfisz oamaommll>uzdoo mo 99mm cm9us How .¢¢Ima mmm umm cuo9 Hm>m cmuoaano mo Hm9as: mCaocmSamca muouumm mo mam>amcm mnu mo muaSmwm .cm ma9mB coma "coama>aw .mmamEmm mua93 omaunmfilum>m ccc.a .am>ma mc. may 9m OHmN Eoum ucmummwao >apcmoamacmamI ooo. mmo. pom. oam. . . . . .ono omumm mom mum 0:3 .oouma mom .mmamEmm muanz omauumelum>m mo usmoumm *ooo.mu omo.: mom. oom.an . . . . .A xv omuma mom mum 0:3 .oouma mom .mmamfimm mua93 omanumfilum>m mo ucmonmm *Noa.m moa. ooo. ooo. . . . . . .Anxo ommoaoam mum 0:3 >ucooo ca .um>o ocm «a mmm .mmamEmm wuacz mo unmoumm *mmfiINI mONI' HHOI ONOIII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I AQXV ”“GSOU How mEouca aMGOmHmQ wamEmm m9a93 Gmaomz «omm.mu ooN.: mac. mvc.| . . . . . . .Amxv mEooca >aaEmm mua93 cmaomz *cmm.o| vmm.l omm.a mom.ma| . .Avxv um>o cam mm mmm .mmamamo ocm mmamE mua93 >9 omumamEoo aoonom mo mumm> cmaomz oom.a mma. mom. oom. . . . . . . Amxo swamu0m ocm mumuonma aumm mum 093 monom no9ma mama mua93 mo ucmoumm 4 mom.l mmo.: am¢. oma.l . . . . . . Amxv mummmcma Eumm can mHmEHmm O mum 093 mouow 909ma mama mua93 mo unmonmm 4 *aom.mn ooo.- omo.m mmo.ou . . . . . . . . .Aaxc mocmcaEOo cmoaaoooupmz *cmm.n .... moa.a¢o mNm.¢mmo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Emma ucmumcoo mmsam> u mucmao coauma>mc mucmaoammmoo mma9maum> unmocmmwoca owusmfioo Iammmov Unmocmum coammmummm mumm amauumm *mnm I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I golfiymcnflgumumg mHQHpA—Hsz MO “Gmfl UHMMGOU mao.cma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . mumEaumm o0 uouum oumocmum *thII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I “cmfloflmmmoo COflgmHmHuoo mHQHUHSS coma "Geama>ao oamaumm Il>ucsoo mo 99mm EHMMQOCIamusu How ovvlma mmm .mmamEmm m9a93 omauumEIum>m ccc.a umm cuo9 Hm>m cmnoaa9u mo Hm965: maaocmSamca muouumm mo mam>amcm map mo muaSmmm .am ma9me .am>ma no. 099 um oumN Souo ucmumooao >aucmoaoacmam* >m¢.I mfic.l aaw. wcm.l . . . . .Amxv mmlmm 0mm mum 093 .wfilma 0mm ~mmamSmo mua93 omauumSIum>m o0 unmoumm «ovm.m| mmN.: mmo. mmo.a| . . . . .Amxv wmlma 0mm mum 093 ~Sulma 0mm .mmamSmo moa93 omouumSIum>m o0 ucmoumm uoo.u oou. moo. ooo. . . . . . .Ahxo omuoaoam mum 0:3 upcsoo so .um>o ocm va mm .mmamSmo mua93 o0 ucmuumm QBBII mmOIl HNOI GHOII I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I onv hpgou uoo mSOUQu amCOmumm mamSmo mua93 cmaomz oooo.mu ooo.: omo. ooo.: . . . . . . .Amxo maoocfl >auamo mounz amuomz *mmc.¢l cmm.: aoo.m mmn.ca| . .Avxv um>0 ocm mm 0mm .mmamSmo ocm mmamS mua93 >9 omumamSoo a009om o0 mumm> cmaomz aoo.. cmc. ccm. amm. . . . . . . Amxv cmSmuoo mam mumu09ma Sumo mum 093 mouoo u09ma mamS mua93 o0 unmoumm 5 omv.l omo.! hmm. mca.l . . . . . . Amxv mummmcmS Sumo Ucm mumSumo % mum 093 mouoo u09ma mamS mua93 o0 unmoumm ooo.uu mou.s moo.m moo.mu . . . . . . . . .Aaxo muomcuaoo cmuoaooouumz *©¢0Im I II I mmHIfimh MBMImmONn I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I gum“ pgmumcoo mmsam> u mucmao GOHuma>mQ mucmaoaoomou mma9maum> uzmocmmmoca omuSQSoo Iaoomoo Uumocmum COHmmmummm mumm amauumm *OOMI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I nonfipmgflaumumm mlflmnflgnfigz MO “QmHUHmmmOU MFHINNN I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I mHMEHgmm mo HOHHm UHMUgmum *flmmI I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I pamnofionoflmmmoo COflpmHmHHO-flv QHQHHHHJZ coma ":0ama>ao oaoaomm I|>ucsoo o0 uumm Sumolamusu uoo .fidlma 0mm ~mmamSmo muu93 omuuumSIum>m ccc.a umm cu09 um>m cmuoaa90 o0 u09S5: mcuocmSaoCa muouumo o0 mam>amcm 099 o0 muaSmmm .mm ma9mB APPENDIX B CHECKLIST FOR SELECTING STUDIES FOR INTENSIVE REVIEW ll. 407 CHECKLIST FOR SELECTING STUDIES FOR INTENSIVE REVIEW Reference: Type of study: Causal (attempts to determine factors affecting fertility) Descriptive (attempts to establish relationships with fertility) Other: Source of data: Census: Survey sample (size and nature of S: Other: Unit of analysis: What country (U.S.?) or parts of country included in study: Period of time or date of study (when data originally collected): The basic problem: General hypothesis(es): Measure(s) of fertility: Independent variables (used in present thesis): Relationship Measure: with Fertility (a) Occupation: (b) Female Employment: (c) Education: (d) Income: (e) Age: (f) Distance: Independent variables (extraneous to present thesis): . Relationship Variable Measure: with Fertility: 12. l3. 14. 15. l6. 17. 408 Are residence categories used? What are the categories? Findings: Contributions to rural or urban social structure: Are color categories used? What are the categories? Findings: Control variables: How used and findings: Statistical techniques: Selected bibliographic references (empirical studies only): Remarks, summary and/or evaluation of study, quotable quotes (give page no.):