AN ECONOMIC STUDY OF THE EASTERN BEET SUGAR INDUSTRY Thesis for the Degree IéfrPh. D. MlCHlGAN STATE UNIVERSITY Robe” Alton Young 19.63 THESIS ,_ ,,A —/’/l’ , I/r/I/fl Th'eflréquiremems for _2h..D.._.degree W31 Economics Major of so: 1);” July 9, 1963 0469 LIBRARY Michigan Sm: University LIBRARY M MW”! 8 I!” U lei-vanity ABSTRACT AN ECONOMIC STUDY OF THE EASTERN BEET‘SUGAR.INDUSTRI by Robert Alton Young Beet sugar production in the Eastern Region (Michigan. Ohio, Indiana, Illinois and Wisconsin) has in the last three decades been characterized by a decline in the level of production. both absolutely and relative to other areas. The purpose of this study has been to make an analysis of the factors influencing the industry in order to determine its future prospects. Changes which provided for increased supplies of sugar from the sugar beet section.were made in the Sugar Act in.l962. This new situation raised questions concerning the possibilities of expansion of beet sugar output in the Eastern Region. Thus, this investigation was made with special reference toward evaluation of the feasibility of proposals for expanded production. The method of analysis was to examine the economic, technical and institutional factors influencing the supply, demand and price of beet sugar in the Eastern.Region. The analysis focused on conditions in.Michigan and Ohio. for in none of the other states has a sugar beet processing industry survived. A study of production response for sugar beets was made using the linear programming technique with variable prices. Production of sugar beets has undergone a major transformation in the past decade. The crop enjoys a strong competitive advantage over other typical crops. Robert Alton Young on the heavy, level lake-bed soils in East Central Michigan and Northwest Ohio. However, high hauling costs limit this advantage to areas adjacent to beet factory locations. The linear programming analysis showed that supplies of beets would be expected to increase to the limits of present factory capacity. As large expansion in processing capacity through erection of new’plants is of questionable profitability (see below). these supplies are likely to be adequate for prospective processing capacity. Beet sugar processors have been faced with rising costs of labor and other resources. Sugar prices as controlled by the Depart- ment of Agriculture under authority of the Sugar Act have not risen as rapidly. Quality of the sugar beets has declined over the last decade as farmers have increased fertilizer use and adopted mechanical harvesting techniques. The factories in the Eastern Region are older and relatively small. However, the construction of new plants entails a capital outlay of 15 to 20 million dollars. An analysis was made of the feasibility of construction of new sugar beet plants. Under Eastern Region conditions. it does not appear that the returns from such a venture would be sufficient to justify the investment. Beet sugar producers in the Eastern.Region supply only a small proportion of the huge Mddwestern.market for sweeteners. They are thus "price takers" and their level of returns is influenced by the behavior of the larger suppliers from coastal cane sugar refineries and Central and western.Region beet sugar producers. Increasing output of beet sugar'in other regions has resulted in the Robert Alton Young surpluses from these areas being shipped into the Midwest. Price concessions have been required in order to penetrate these markets. ‘A statistical analysis showed that these supplies have a measurable impact on returns to Eastern.Region beet processors and growers. Basis prices in the region are often lower than elsewhere in the nation. This condition is partially offset by a freight advantage. It was concluded that the outlook for the beet sugar industry in the Eastern Region is for neither a period of rapid growth nor for an immediate demise. A period of favorable prices and continued technological advances are in the offing fer the sugar beet farmer. The sugar beet processor can expect a somewhat larger supply of beets to enable a more effective utilization of capacity. A period of favorable price levels should exist for several seasons until world supplies are brought into closer balance with consumption. These factors should help offset the continued increases in resource costs and.the decline in the quality of the sugar beets. AN ECONOMIC STUDY OF THE EASTERN BEET SUGAR INDUSTRY ' by Robert Alton Young A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1963 (,K) 1 (A1“ \ . WW5 The author wishes to express his appreciation to the many people who have assisted with various phases of this study and made its completion possible. Thanks are particularly due to Professor Glenn L. Johnson for his guidance and encouragement throughout the course of the study. The author is indebted to Dr. L. L. Boger, Chairman of the Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, for arranging the financial resources which made the study possible. Funds in support of the project were provided by the Marketing Economic Research Division, Economic Research Service, of the U.S. Department of Agriculture, and by the Agricultural Experiment Station, Michigan State University. Dr. Roy A. Ballinger of the Marketing Economic Research Division, U.S. Department of Agriculture, assisted with the research project at a number of points and read and criticized portions of the final manuscript. / Assistance and constructive criticisms were generously given by numerous members of the staff of the College of Agriculture. Particular thanks are due to Dr. V. L. Sorensen for his help and guidance during the final phase of the work. Professors Clifford Ifildreth, Leonard Kyle and Karl Wright criticized earlier drafts. Milton Erdman and L. S. Robertson of the Departments of Farm Crops and Soil Science, respectively, gave freely of their time and knowledge. ii Appreciation is also expressed to those in the beet sugar industry who provided data and other assistance. P. A. Reeve and G. E. Nichol were particularly helpful. Thanks are given to Mrs. Arlene King, Laura Flanders, and others of the computing staff for their competent and cheerful assistance in the compilation, processing and summarization of the data and computations, to hrs. Lynn Rooks for typing of portions of an earlier draft, and to Mrs. Helen Rishoi for her patience and care in typing the final manuscript. The cooperation of the many growers and processors of sugar beets and the users of sugar from whom the data was collected is gratefully acknowledged. Finally, the author wishes to thank his wife, Lynn, for her patience and encouragement, during the preparation and completion of the study and for the countless hours she spent in typing and proofing the manuscript. Any errors which remain in the manuscript are the respons- ibility of the author. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS AKNW T O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 0 LIST OF m 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O HST OF APPENDIXE O 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O 04-. O O O 0 Chapter I . II . V. INmODUCHON C O O O O O O I O O O O O O O O O O HISTORICAL, ECONOMIC AND POIITICAL BACKGROUND . . A. B. C. D. E. General - About Sweeteners . . . . . . . Sugar Beet Production in the Eastern Region................ Economic Characteristics of the Market forSugar............... The United States Government and the SugarIndustry ............ International Markets in Sugar . . . . . SUGAR BEET PRODUCTION RESPONSE I: TECHNOLOGY AND R$OURCE ORGANIZA‘HON A. B. C. IntrOductory O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Technical Aspects of Sugar Beet Production in the Eastern Region . Resource Organization and Supplies . SUGAR BEST PRODUCTION RESPONSE II: ANALYTICAL MODEL.......'............... A. B. C. D. Static'Model of Production Response inSugarBeetS............ Results of the Static Linear Programming AWSis O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Other Influences on Production Response . Summary and Conclusions from the Analysis of Production Response . . . . SUGAR BET PROCESING O O O O O O O O O O O O O O A. The Production Process and Input-Output RelationShiPSeoeoeeeeoeeoo iv Page ii 11 16 30 39 57 69 69 86 96 109 112 112 Chapter Page B. Returns to Alternative Methods ofAddingPlantCapacity........ 119 VI. MARKETING, DISTRIBUTION AND DEMAND . . . . . . . . 130 A. Sources of Supply and Channels of DiStributiOnooeeeeeeeeooeel3o B. Components of Demand for Sugar . . . . . . 138 C. Sugar Pricing and Prices . . . . . . . . . 145 VII 0 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 0 e e e e e e o e o e e e 164 BIBLIOGRAPHY e o e e o e e e e e o. e o e o e e e o o e e e 147 MW e e e e e e e o e e e e e e e o e e e e o e e 179 Table 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 205 2.6 3.1 3.2 3-3 3.# 3-5 306 4.1 #.2 LIST OF TABLES Beet sugar factories in operation in the EaStern Region, 1900-1963 e e e o e e e o o e e e o e Acreage and production of sugar beets and production of refined beet sugar, U.S. by states, SBlGCtedyearseoeeoeeeoeeeeeeeeoe Wbrld sugar production (in 1,000 of metric tons, raw value). Crop years beginning March 1 . . . . . . Selected estimates of price and income elasticity Ofdemandforsugar......o.......... world centrifugal sugar consumption, 1959 . . . . . . Wholesale prices of sugar compared with indices of prices of all foods and of per capita disposable incomagl935-6200090000eeeeeoooeee Selected temperature and precipitation data, three Stations in EaStern Beet area 0 e e e e e e e 0 Expected average yields per acre, sugar beets and competing crops under improved practices on selected soil management groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Acres blocked and thinned per worker per season: four Michigan Factory Districts, 1955-62 . . . . . . Classification of Survey Farms by size and type . . . Land use on surveyed farms: average acres per fambycrOpSeeeeeeeeeeeeeoeeeooe Resources on representative farm situations . . . . . Projected costs and returns per acre to sugar beets and competing crops, Michigan and Ohio dismctS. 1966 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Selected physical inputs per acre,sugar beets and competing crops, Michigan and Ohio districts, projectiontol966 ................. Page 14 15 l? 21 31 52 61 62 6t; 77 78 Table 4.3 4.4 “.5 “.6 4.7 #.8 5.1 5.2 5-3 5.4 5-5 6.1 6.2 6.3 Projected optimal resource organization and investments-~medium field crop farm without livestock, Saginaw Valley-"Thumb," Michigan, 1966(Ca561)eoeeeeeeeeooeeoeee Projected optimal resource organization and inwestments--medium.field crop farm with.live- stock, Saginaw'Valley-"Thumb," Michigan, 1966(Ca562)eeeeeeeeeeeeoeoeee Projected optimal resource organization and investments--field crop farm, Northwestern Ohi0.1966eeeeeeoeeoeeeoooeeo Effect of distance to sugar beet factory on proportion of farms growing beets, 1960 . . . . . Distribution of su ar beet farmers by distance to delivery point factory or railroad loading point), Michigan and Ohio, 1960 . . . . . . . . . Measures of variability of gross income per acre for sugar beets, dry beans, corn, 1946-61 . . . . Production and related labor requirements for three hypothetical sugar beet factories . . . . . Physical inputs and cost assumptions for hypothetical beet sugar factories . . . . . . . . Capital investments for three hypothetical plants Income and expenses per ton of boots sliced, hyPOtheucalfactorj-eseeeeeeeeeeeoe Income and expense statement for hypothetical fac'borieseeeooe-eoeoeeoeeeeeee United States sugar receipts and production, bysourceofsupply,1962............ Distribution of direct consumption sugar by primary distributors, 1962 . . . . . . . . . . . Domestic shipments of corn sweeteners, selected years...................... Page 88 9O 93 98 98» 104 122 123 125 131 132 134 Table 6.4 6.5 6.6 6.7 6.8 609 Page Total and per capita sugar distribution by primary distributors for consumption in the U.S.,Selectedyearso.............. 137 Deliveries of sugar by type of buyer, 1949-62 . . 140 Sugar deliveries by type of product or business or buyer, calendar year, 1962 e e e e e e e e o e 142 Receipts,production and distribution of sugar by states and regions, October, 1961, September, 1962. 1.000 Me. refined value 0 e e e e e e o e 153 Beet sugar production, U.S., and beet sugar distribution, East North Central states . . . . . 156 Selected cane and beet sugar wholesale prices, with tax, by areas, annual average, 1947-62 . . . 159 viii LIST OF APPENDEXES Appendix Page I Chronological History of Beet Sugar FaCtOries in the EaStern Region 0 e e e e e e e 180 II Table 8 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 184’ CHAPTER I NC N The Department of Agriculture classifies sugar beet producing regions as "Eastern," "Central" and "Western." The Eastern Region is comprised of Michigan, Ohio, Wisconsin, Illinois and Indiana. The last decade or two has witnessed major transformations in the conditions under which the boot sugar industry in the United States operates. Some of these changes are technologcal; others are the result of economic shifts, and others may be termed political or institutional. Marv of these have affected the whole of the industry, but a number are localized in the Eastern Region. As background for the problem, let us briefly sketch the nature of some of the changes. Sugar Beet Pmductionw-Tne sugar beet crop has long been known as a high cost, labor intensive enterprise. In the past two decades research work by the United States Department of Agriculture, the land grant colleges and experiment stations and the sugar industry has resulted in dramatic changes in the production technolog of the sugar beet. Since the introduction and complete adoption of mechani- cal harvesting techniques, the heavy demands for migrant labor in the harvest periods are a thing of the past. Research in plant breeding and in mechanical and chemical weed control show great promise of simi- lar elimination of hand labor for "spring work." Per-acre yields are also advancing due to more intensive use of resources, improved varieties, and shifts to more favorable locations. These yield increases are taking place more rapidly in the Eastern Region than elsewhere, so that state average yields per acre have on occasion in recent years exceeded those of some of the irrigamd areas of states farther to the west. W.—Major technological advances and increased capi- tal inveth are evident in the processing sector as well. However, the apparently optimisuo outlook for the beet grower is not completely mirrored in the Eastern Region processors' situation. be last two decades have witnessed a decline in the region's sugar production both relative to other areas and absolutely. Michigan, once a major center of beet sugar production, has fallen from third among the states in the middle flairties to a position of seventh in 1962. Factory mmbers in that state have dropped from sixteen in 191» to five in 1962. Ohio's rank has also declined somewhat, and the last remaining plant in Wisconsin did not slice beets in 1962. Even after this reduction in capacity some processors are unable to contract as much acreage as their capacity warrants. However, these figures do not tell all the story. Much of the decline in production and number of factories can be attributed to inappropriate location of factories relative to raw material supplies. The remaining factories appear to be in localities where beets enjoy a more favorable competitive position. New invest- ment ani fruits of research have increased the daily and annual slic- ing capacity so that the output of the present eight plants slightly succeeds that of the 22 plants in Michigan and Ohio in 1925. Ww—Sugar produced in Michigan and Ohio supplies only a small portion of the total consumption of these states. About 35 percent of all sugar delivered in Michigan is of local origin, and the figure is typically between 10 and 15 percent for Ohio. the five states of the region absorb nearly one-fourth of sugar deliveries in the U.S. Less than 8 percent of this huge market is accounted for by the Eastern Beet Sugar Industry. Location in such a deficit market is favorable to Eastern Region producers, but other factors operate to reduce this advantage. In recent years there have been supplies of Central and Western beet sugar in excess of the demand in those regions. Surplus sugar has come East to Chicago and the nearby areas, and price concessions have been necessary in order to penetrate this market mich is also supplied by cane refiners on the Atlantic and Gulf Coasts. Competition is intensified in Southern Lower Michigan by a freight rate structure which is more favorable from certain Rocky Mountain points to that area than to Chicago. The Southwestern Lower Michigan sugar. market has come to be known as the “coffin corner“ in the trade. On the demand side of the marketing picture, the major con- suners of sugar are now the “industrial users"; the food surfing and frees-ing, baking, dairy products, cum and beverage industries now absorb over 60 percent of the United States' annual consumption of sugar. these new markets pose new problems to the sellers of sugar. hey denmd a wider range of products which met meet more exacting specifications. munch me political front, the sugar industry operates under what is probably the most complex and extensive set of regula- tions of an agricultural commodity. A number of important changes have been put into effect in the Federal sugar regulations, particularly as they relate to the future growth of the domestic beet industry's share of the sugar market. he presence of an unfriendly regime in Cuba, long a major supplier of sugar for the United States, has required that other sources of supply be found. Among the steps in this direction has been a change in the provisions of the sugar legislation which will enable the erection of several new beet sugar factories in the United States. Neg Sugar beets and beet sugar do not account for a large portion of the farm income of the Eastern Region or even of the producing states in the Region. However, for the several thousand farmers who grow beets in Michigan and Ohio, the best sugar processing industry is a major market, and in the communities in which the processing facilities are located, the industry is an important part of the local economy. the changing econodc and technical conditions focused attention on the value of an econouc study of the industry. In 1961, largely through the foresight of personnel at Michigan State University, the present stuck was initiated with the purpose of making an economic investigation of a nuaber of the problems confronting the Eastern Beet Sugar Industry. Since that time, the study has taken on a new and inediate significance. Because of the potential effects of further shut-downs of plants to the farmers and localities concerned, individuals and groups at local and state levels have also become concerned that the down-trend in best sugar factory mmbers might be continuing. More recently, the provisions in the 1962 Federal sugar legis- lation for additional sugar beet acreage and plant capacity have resulted in proposals for construction of new processing facilities in the Eastern Beet Area. The capital outlay envisioned in these proposals is of the order of 15 to 20 million dollars. It is obvious that unwise investment could entail capital losses of large magnitude. The alter- native of expanding existing facilities also has its proponents. It is therefore important that a careful analysis of the factors influenc- ing the outcome of all alternative courses of action be available to the parties concerned. W the foregoing brief discussion of the industry points up some important characteristics of the Eastern Beet Sugar Industry. no small proportion of the market which it can supply dictates that producers in the region are ”price-takers." me market is mainly influenced by supplies from cane refiners on the Atlantic and Gulf Coasts and from beet sugar producers to the West. he conceptual framework appropriate to the subsequent analysis is the theory of interregional trade, which is the modern refinement of the theory of comparative advantage. The pure theory may be sma- marised as follows: more are a set of regions with different resource endowments trading in some homogeneous good. Positive transportation costs exist between regions. Composite supply and demand schedules are visualized for each region for the product in question. An equilibrium solution would indicate (a) the net price in each region, (b) the quantity of exports and imports of the good in each region, and (c) the volume and direction of trade in the good between each possible pair of regions.:L PreliIdnary Considerations Geographical Area - Enpirical estimation of supply and demand relations for sugar for each of the several regions of the United States is an enterprise beyond the scope of this study. the analysis will be confined to a consideration of such relaflonships for the areas presently producing sugar beets in the five states of the Eastern Beet Sugar Region.2 Marketing Stage - The price-making forces may be examined at a number of steps in the channels from farm to consumer. In this case, the forces affecting both the price of sugar beets and the price of sugar Idll betreated. Supply In the static theory of the firm, the supply relation for a given product is determined by (a) the price of the product, (b) the cost of resources required in its production, and (c) the production function (the relationship between resources and output), given, of 1mm- s. Enke, “Equilibrium Among Spatially Separated Markets,” . Vol. 19. No. 1. January, 1951. 3.. also Ronald Highell “Jon De m“. ~’. ' .". ‘. - .' '1 CM.’ Mass" Harvard University Press, 193., Chapter 2. 231m the field mm» for this project were completed, some interest in the beet industry has been evidenced in Eastern Region states not now producing beets (Indiana, Illinois and also New York). file data in this stuck relating to sugar beet production applies only to Mchigan and Ohio areas presently growing beets. This information has some relevance to conditions elsewhere in the region but should be interpreted with considerable care for such applications. course, the usual assumptions of a profit-madmizing firm under conditions of perfect knowledge.l Uncertainty, fixed factors, capital rationing, nomonetary goals, multi-product firms and complementary and supplementary relation- ships are complicating factors which must be taken into account. mese general principles apply to both the farm and the process- ing firms in the present case. Accordingly, the analysis of the supply side of the equation shall consider technical prohction relationships and the price and supplies of resources for both the production of sugar beets and competing enterprises and for the processing of the best crop. Institu‘uonal restraints on sugar supplies are of major importance in the present case. A thorough examination of Federal sugar policy thus is necessary for the understanding of sugar supplies and prices. Demand Final demand for a product is considered to be chum by consumer preferences and incomes. In the case under consideration, it has been noted that a large proportion of sugar purchases are for industrial uses. his demand is I'derived" from the demand for the various sugar containing final products. The nature and elasticities of these markets differ. Accordingly, the characteristics of each of these markets require separate attention. 1%, m1 0.. In... and Concepts in Supply Analysis," in Earl 0- M. 9—411:- -. «18.. W Arm. Iowa, Iowa State University Press, 1 1. W The objective of this thesis is, then, to present the results of a stub of the economic factors influencing the Eastern Beet Sugar Industry. In view of the current requirements, the analysis will be carried out in terms of the problems of and potential for expansion of the acreages of sugar boots and plant capacity in the region. These objectives will be approached in the following steps: 1. In Chapter II, the historical and economic background will be described, and the development and operation of the federal sugar programs will be discussed. 2. InChaptersIIIandIV, ananalysiswillbemadeofthe projected future competitive position and expected supply relation- ships for sugar beets in the region. 3. Chapter V will examine certain econondn relations in the processing sector as they relate to supply and price of sugar. 4. me characteristics of the sugar market Idll be described in Chapter VI and an analysis made of the special conditions affect- ing the marketing of sugar in ma... where Eastern beet sugar 1. sold. 5. In Chapter VII, the estimates and analysis of previous steps will be integrated and conclusions drawn about the prospective position of the Eastern Beet Sugar Industry. CHAPM II HISMIC, ECONOMIC AND POLIHCAL MWD A. General - About Sweeteners be class of compounds which the chemists call I'sugars" or 'saccharides" are members of the larger group of organic compounds termed carbotydrates (that is, mounds these molecules are formed from atoms of carbon, hydrogen and oxygen). Sugar molecules have a unique structure and arrangement of the atoms of these elements . he simplest sugars, which are called momosaccharides, usually have five to seven carbon atoms in a molecule and about two hydrogen and one oxygen atom for each of carbon. A semen example of the mono- saccharids is dextrose (also called glucose) which has the formula C5H1205. Honcsaccharides may combine to form higher sugars ('oligo- saccharides'). me disaccharide of formula 012322011. termed I'sucrose,” is the product which is co-cnly called Huger." It is a usually stable combination of the two monosaccharides, dextrose and levulose. Hencefcrth, unless otherwise specified, in this discussion the term 'sugar' will be used to refer to sucrose in its various forms. me only commercially important sources of sucrose are the sugarbeetandsugarcaneplants. As the sucroseisintheplantin pure form, the process of recovery is one of extraction, rather than of chdoal modification. The refined product of either process is chemically identical and only an exhaustive laboratory analysis of 10 the tixw amount of residual impurities can differentiate between the two. RefinedcanesugarconsumedintheumudStatesisusuallythe result of two processings. The sugar cane stalks are crushed at a cane mill, and there a ”raw sugar“ of about 97 percent purity is recovered. The final refining usually is accomplished in large refineries located in various large seaboard cities. The sucrose is usually produced in crystalline form, although some cane refineries are equipped to produce a liquid sugar which does not pass through the crystalline stage. In the crystalline form it maybegrounduptobecome powdered sugar oritmayberedissolvedto become a liquid sugar. The 'brown' or 'soft' sugars are composed of very fine crystals of sucrose with highly refined sirups added to give the special flavor and consistency. when a sugar in water solution is treated by heating in the presence of acids or certain enzymes, the sucrose breaks down into its two components, dextrose and levulose. nae resulting solution has less of a tendency to crystallize than sugar and is valued in certain industrial uses such as candy-making and beverage-bottling. This process of breaking down sucrose is called "inversion,'I all the resulting product is known as 'invert sugar." Other saccharides of cosmercial importance are those refined from the hydrolysis of starch (usually cornstarch). Dextrose (identical to one of the components of sucrose) is a monosaccharide produced by a complete ludrolysis or conversion. It is not considered to be as sweet as sucrose but has other useful properties. Partial We of cornstarch can result in a prochact known as I'corn sirup.‘I It contains chiefly dextrose, maltose and higher saccharides. Several grades are 11 produced. depending largely upon the total reducing sugar content of the sirup. his sirup also say be dehydrated to produce “corn sirup solids“ which has nary uses in industrial food manufacturing. Certain other organic compounds have been found to has sweeten- ing properties. Saccharin and certain cyclamates are the nest common examples. These compounds substitute for saccharides in dietary uses since they have no caloric content but a relatively large sweetening power. Hence. they are termed “non-caloric” sweeteners. Uses of Sweeteners The main function of sweeteners is as a flavoring. Besides having an attractive taste in themselves. they enhance and bring out the flavors of other foods tdth which they nay be combined. hey can also serve as a preservative. as in Jane or Jellies. In baking. sugar provides food for yeasts. and the desirable brown color on the crusts of baked goods comes from the cancellation of sugar from the heat of the oven. B. Beet Sugar Production in the lastern Region he first attempts at beet production for sugar in the United States occurred in the 1830's in Pennsylvania and later in Massachusetts and Michigan. Several other efforts got underway in the next three decades before the California Beet Sugar Manufacturing Conpuv com- nenced operations at Alvarado. California. in 1870. This factory is called the first successful beet sugar plant in the United States. for a factory (since completely rebuilt) is presently operating on the original site. 12 In the meantime. a number of other factories were estab- lished. leaning upon the European experience for both equipment and knowledge. he industry during this developmental stage was given important encouragement from the Department of Agriculture. James ulson. who was Secretary of Agriculture under three Prehidents. and Dr. Harvey W. Riley. Chief Chemist of the Department for nearly 1K) years. instituted research programs to determine the best locations and methods for beet production and worked unceasingly to encourage new capital investment in beet sugar factories. he revenue tariffs on sugar in the Nineteenth Century provided some protection from cane sugar imports to the fledgling beet sugar industry. when these tariffs were repealed for a short period. a bounty replaced them. Under these influences a great number of best sugar enterprises sprang up. Seventy-one factories were built during a 10-year period. 1897- 1906.1 Valey's studies indicated that the best climate for the sugar beetwasinanareawherethemeansmmler temperature fallsbetween 67° and 72%.2 In 1898 he produced a map which delineated the most favored areas. he regions so designated included the areas near the Great Lakes. across the Northern Great Plains. below both Eastern and western Slopes of the Rocky Mountains. ad along the Pacific Coast in California. It is interesting to note that most of the sugar beet lUnited States Department of Agriculture. Sugar Division. "..'. ‘ . _ _. ' -- i- Washington. D.C.. 1%1e 20. 3. House of Representatives. 55th Congress. 2nd Session. Documentlo.3%. S ~- 8-, e-s - ington. D.C.. Gov't. Printing Office. l898. 13 operations remaining at the present time are located within the areas specified 65 years ago by Wiley} A siseable portion of the industry's development in that period at the turn of the century was in the Great Lakes area. particularly in Michigan. (Of the 71 new beet sugar factories reported in the decade from 1897 to 1906. 22 were in Michigan and nine were in the other Great Lakes States.) be large expansion in Michigan was partly a reflection of a bounty of one cent per pound offered by the Michigan Legislature in 1897.2 Since the early burst of expansion in Michigan. the center of gravity of beet sugar prochiction has been moving westward. As shown in Table 2.1. new factories in the region around the Great Lakes region have ceased operations. Meamdnile. new plants opened and existing plants expanded capacity in the Plains. Mountain and Western states. Table 2.2 shows that the decline in production in the Eastern Region has been even more striking when related to the growth in total production of best sugar in the United States. California and Colorado have maintained their position of leadership in total sugar production while Idaho. Minnesota. Washington and Montana have moved up in the rankings ahead of Michigan. Beet production in Indiana and ascensin has ceased and only a relatively small acreage is still produced in Illinois. ISee. United States Department of Agriculture. Farmer's Bulle- tinNc. 2060. Nu, - 2 9 . C - Sta . Wash- ington. 13.0.. 19 2hr an interesting first-hand account of the origin and development of the beet sugar industry in the Great Lakes area. see Oviatt. C. R... "Sixty Years in Sugar.” U.S. Department of Agriculture. A353. W No. 128. December. 1962. -.l ll} m 2.1. BEET SUGAR memes IN ommon IN the mm may. 1900—19631 1900 10 1 1 1 o 1905 20 1 3 1 o 1910 17 2 u 1 o 1915 16 5 a 1 1 1920 l? 5 5 1 1 1925 17 5 4 1 o 1930 16 5 1+ o o 1935 16 5 2 o 0 19116 16 5 2 o 0 19195 11» a 1 o o 1950 13 4 1 0 0 1955 9 3 1 o o 1960 5 3 1 o o 1963 5 3 0 o o lDerived primarily from 0.3.11.1" Sugar Division. W W Washington. 13.6.. 1961. 15 .soween .32” e5 nevus 33.3:er neeeeo gone! s." Esau «San-lea Dunc a? .33: go s." neeoeooad she .3 use wean .303 5.8: a." 8.88.1 3.8 .388 Show 8. .388 .13 5 588.3 us announces v.3 53 3315 \u dean—sauce: .396 neon .3. an. a8." £3.38 a; :19»... :8... 33.8.: Hans-33m .8983 :33 63.85am can .3 .65 .382 Sam ween shoves: “eons—om} and: $13 8.3 838 88.3 mm» 3.8 98.3 a 88.8 Rafi Rm .3. .38 mama 38.." m3 3...... 1.3.." R Ra.“ an. mm 33 :8 8 >133... .850 .3 o Won min an." d 3H mfi 9 8n n3 3 gonad mama \ can; «in 3a in H8 8n n.” «an Eu 3 songs: {an an... d 8H mead 3m 2 m8; 8.. an a man on $8.83. an; “.3 8 an cu m." a 8m 8 «8 88 R 38 an; «as in can; an“ R a8; 8n .3 «NJ as an .35 .5; as 8 SQ." was on m3; 8... 8 and... :8 an anion. Rn.“ main 5 when new; 8 End in; 8 wand «24 E 3.3 8%.. m8 2. one; 82. 8 n8; n8 8 8a.~ a.” k. stun; «8.... n8 Mm 88.“... So an inn .8 2. «86 a8 8 833. 8a.... a8; 8 83 E 3 1.8.... 3m 8 tin m8; «Na Susan. 32 85.... .5 «88 1.8; an “an.“ 8.3 and 81» 8.~ Ra 8.83 «8.3 8n... .3 82$ «.8... 8H anus Sn.“ and «in.» «mod «3 €888 .r . a..- an..- n «a. ;.. . . .. a... u .q a. .. w an « --.. .45..- u 83 h 83 n 83 n 83 . o8H. 83 n 83 i .88 n 83 . o8a . o8a . 83 . .11.. “.66 insane. .. one 7.3.... 1.1-. ”.11.. 7- «1. .. 31.... .4... a noamuuoamsuaemnuoamnneamnnaem”noninfeamanaemnsoam. teaming. gamma-ween. one 35.3338“ ems «newsmatem» ewe anew—5.33m” ewe a veemnaemsmaueaod.»eemaneusn.gasgagagaaeaagag. E . :. n 1.....- x 84H Bond» .35.. B .m. o .38 a Bag .8 2.50808 8.4 .85 38 8 85088.. 9: 836a .~.~ a 16 C. Economic Characteristics of the Market for Sugar Production and Supply Cane sugar supplies about 55 percent of the total world market of 56 Iillion tons of centrifugal sugar (see Table 2.3). the agri- cultural organizations which produce cane and beet sugar show a rather remarkable contrast. Both the cane stalk and the boot root are relatively perishable and bulky so that the sugar fills must be located in the groping areas. Sugar cane is usually grown in a nonocultural system. with vast tracts around the raw sugar mills devoted entirely to the culture of cane. Sugar beets. on the other hand. typically are included in a livestock-crop rotation agriculture in temperate climates. he crop is grown by individual farmers under contract to a factory. nae neces- sity of growing best: as part of an extended crop rotation nukes it unfeasible for a factory to own and operate an agricultural operation of the scope necessary to provide the raw material for a factory. A factory processing 2,000 tons of beets per day for 100 days must draw upon 50 to 75 thousand acres of adapted cropland (assuming 16 tons per acre yield and a rotation of it to 6 years duration). lhe by-prodncts of the sugar beet harvest (beet tops) and of sugar extraction (beet pulp and molasses) all find value in livestock feeding operations. Supply Response in Sugar Isa-ination of the history of the sugar industry there free market forces have been allowed to reign show that supplies of sugar have been very inelastic to increases in price within the production mm 2.3. m SUGAR PRODUCTION“ (IN 1.000 or MEMO TONS. m VALUE). (:30? YEARS BEGINNING MARCH 1 8.. Europe Beet Cane 0.8.3 .3. Beet North and Central America including Caribbean Beet Cane Hon-centrifugal Cane South America Beet Cane Non-centrifugal Cane m. (including Mainland China and Oceania) Beet Cane Hen-eentrifugal Cane Africa Cane World Totals Beet Cane Total Centrifugal Total lion-centrifugal 11.795 35 6.195 2.165 11.950 315 70 6.175 875 2.555 21.200 28.880 50.080 7.4140 .60 10. 520 30 5.967 2, 260 12,405 310 85 6.100 860 1.135 8.675 5.850 2.675 19.970 29.380 “9.850 7.440 l -6 14. 515 35 6.9156 2. 375 13.690 265 65 6.250 930 1.310 5.805 2,1l-OO 25.210 31.1160 56.670 7.000 "Source: Food ani Agricultural Organisation. United Nations. nan... Italy. 19,61. 18 period. However. the output is very responsive to higher prices over a period long enough for the financing and erection of the necessary milling and transportation equipment. his relationship has been particularly true in the case of cane sugar. due largely. no doubt, to the relatively plentiful supplies of adapted land and of labor in tropi- cal regions. Wolf asserts that tropical countries can expand output tithout increasing costs for a considerable range, providing only that capital is available for mills.1 Declining prices have not resulted in the equivalent reduction in output and the industry in such cases has suffered through long periods of low prices follovdng overexpansions. he theoretical framework developed by Johnson and others provides an explanation of this behavior.2 Briefly. this analysis shows that where resources cannot be disposed of at prices equal to their cost of acquisi- tion. the profit machining firm will not reduce output for some range of falling prices. 'Ihe size of this range depends upon the difference between acquisition and salvage prices of the relevant resources. The case of a sugar mill or a factory demonstrates this property to a striking degree. Processing facilities. and in the cane areas the standing cane crops, are resources which have little or no alternative use when sugar prices fall. When the demand for sugar. and hence the danand for these resources used in sugar production declines. the Wolf. H. A.. e U Sta s Su ar P ts ct 23.93220 Doctoral dissertation. Univ. of Michigan. 1958. Univ. marofiln. Ann Arbor. Michigan. 2See Johnson. Glenn 1... "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis.” ng 9f Fem Econgmics. Vol. 1+2. No. 2. May. 1960. and also Edwards. Clark. "Resource Fixity in Farm Organization,” Jggnal 9; Earn: Ecgnggcs, Vol. #2, No. h, November. 1960. and references cited. l9 salvage values can be quite low. Thus. it is implied that falling ' prices would have relatively little effect on output and general over- investnent in sugar facilities are quite likely to be followed by long periods of chronic heavy stocks and depressed prices. The tendency toward goverment intervention in sugar industries precluded aw extensive test of this proposition. for outpat has been reduced by decree in new countries there the free action of entrepreneurs has failed to do so. he aperience of Cuba in the 1920's is illustrative. Extremely high prices were followed by a short depression which occurred after the wartime levels. spurring large investments in cans milling eqfipaent and plantations. Output Jumped some 12 percent between 1923 and 1924 (using 1921-23 as a base period) and 28 percent more in 1925 as the new fills cane into operation. In the meantim. the high price of 1923 emouraged increases in output elsewhere around the world which caused the price to collapse while the increases in production were occurring. m. relatively large (28 percent) increase in output in 1925 had fol- lowedayearinvdzichpricehaddeclinedbyoverathirdfronthe average level of 1923. Prices continued to decline. dropping down to Ml» percent of the 1923 level in 1925 and remained down in 1926. Prodnc- tion in the leantine did not show a decline until 1926. nearly 2 years after the first price drop. is suggested by the theoretical analysis. this decline was finer relative to the price decline. being on the order of 7 percent. It took action by the Cuban Government to reduce output by a further 10 percent in the 1927 crop. although the price of sugar was but m1: of its value u years previously} 311.11. H. 1.. 31:. s P c 923- 22.2.3.3.- he most important deterfinants of sugar consumption are sugar prices and the income level of common. Data on per capita consumption show considerable variation among nations. nose dif- ferences are largely explained by the income level of various countries. Viton and Plgnalosa of the United Nations Food and Agricultural Organi- sation (FAD) made an exhaustive study of the demand for sugar} They applied statistical regression techniques to both cross-sectional and time series data. as well as sumarizing previous efforts in this field. Sore of their estinates of income and price elasticities are reproduced in Table 2.1+. The estimates for countries classified asto income level showed that changes in income at a relatively low level of per capita income are likely to be associated with a more than proportional change in sugar consumption. while income changes are likely to have such less effect on consumtion in the developed countries. It appears that in a highly developed economy. such as that of the United States. this relation- ship between incomes and consumption becones relatively stable. In the estimates shown in Table 2.1+ for three different periods in the United States. only finer changes have occurred in the income elasticities. 'lhese relationships are also evident in Table 2.5 which presents total axd per capita consunption for various areas in the world. The neasure- nent of price elasticity (the effect of change in price on consumption) also is illnfinating. In low income countries. consunption is quite lViton. A. and Pignalosa. F.. ”bends and Prospects in World Sugar Consumption." f a1 E . Sta gee. Vol. II. Nos. 1 and 2. l 0. FAQ. Bone. Italy. 21 TABLE 2.‘&. SHRED ES'IIMA OF PRICE AND INCOME EASTICITI 0F DEMAND m2 SU : Price : Income = W— Groups of Countries Classified by Income2 Low Income Countries -1.08 1.23 Medium Income Countries -O.86 0.71; High Income Countries -O.37 0A0 United States. Selected Year33 1921 - 1938 .o.3o 0.34 1921 - 1938 plus 19% - 1951 -o.26 0.27 1921 - 1938 Plus 19% - 1956 -0.28 0.27 1v1ton and Pignalosa. 9343.. See also no, United Nations Cmdity Bulletin Series 140- 32. W Wm. Rome. 1961. by the same authors. 2Data from postwar years. Income levels are defined such that Medium Insane Countries are those with per capita income falling between $200 U.S. and $500 U.S. Low Income Countries have per capita incomes below this range. and High Income Countries above it. alias series analysis. responsive to price change; the estimated percentage change in consumption being greater than the percentage change in price. How- ever. in the higher income countries the change in price has relatively little effect on the quantity demanded. In the United States. as iniicated in Table 2.4. the elasticity is estimated to be only about -0.27; that is. only a relatively small change in the quantity denuded is associated with a given change in price. These properties of the demand for sugar suggest that. particularly in high income countries. prices would be quite volatile. and relatively small deficits or sur- pluses in supplies would be reflected in rather large novments in MOOe 22 new 2.5. ms consume» sum CONSUMPTION. 1959l : Total : Per Capita : Consumption : Consumption h“ : (1.000 metric : (pounds =w) 1 v western Europe 10e721 7“ North America 9. 223 105 Central America 1.898 6? Near East (Asia) 1.310 32 Far East 5.819 16 Africa 2.641 24 Oceania 713 101 East Europe and U.S.S.R. 8.556 62 Mainland China 1.300 4 World « 116.728 36 ISouroe: FAG. United Nations. 8 w Rome. Italy. 1961. Table 12-A and Table 12-B. u. no United States'Government and the Sugar Industry s -- a he main interest of the Federal Goverment in the sugar trade during the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries was as a source of income. Inelastic demand and well defined trade channels made sugar an excellent vehicle for gaining revenues. It is reported that the sugar duties during the last century made up nearly 20 per- cent cf all custom collections. A by-product of the tariff was the protection afforded to the infant sugar cane industry of Louisiana and later to the Kingdom of Hawaii. (his latter nation was given duty-free entry under terms of a treaty in 1876.) In 1890. sugar duties were removed but a two cent bounty on domestic sugar afforded protection. In 1891}. when the tariff was 23 reinstated. the duty on sugar was explicitly intended to continue protection of the domestic industry. as well as for revenue.1 Behind the tariff barriers and with the assistance and encouragement of the Department of Agriculture. the domestic beet sugar imstry developed. The Spanish-American War brought new sources of sugar supplies into the United States' market as the new territories of Puerto Rico and the Phillipines received chity-free status. and Cuba was afforded a preferential tariff rate. The economics of these areas. as well as that of Hawaii. soon specialised in cane sugar production. and their econofic well-being was dependent upon both United States' policies and demand for sugar. United States' policy since this time has always been fomlated with explicit references to the responsibility for the well-being of these nations. me industry enjoyed a period of relative stability and growth up to and through the First World War. However. soon after this time. the picture changed. In the early 1920's a period of favorable sugar prices induced large investments in cane producing and processing capacity. particularly in Cuba. Coincidentally. nationalistic policies carried out by several European countries brought recovery to the beet sugar industry in that region. Prices fell rapidly. the supplies continued to increase and subsequently declined only a relatively small amount. so stocks began to accumulate in exporting countries. The United States Congress responded to these conditions by raising the lSee the United States House of Representatives. 53rd Congress. 2nd Session. He s be ttee and Means Document No. 3. Government Printing Office. Washington. 0.0.. 93. 24 tariff three times in order to protect the domestic boot and cans iniustries. The Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930 raised the Cuban duty to two cents per pound of sugar. and to two and one-half cents per pound on sugar from so-called full-duty countries. (Cuban sugar had a 20 percent tariff preferential. which together with Cuba's advantage on shipping rates made Cuban chlty the effective rate.) During the earlier part of the period. the tariff had successfully insulated the domestic industry in the world market. m the 1930's. with a world- wide collapse in demand from the depression. heavy stocks of sugar and continued excess capacity made even the Smoot-Hawley Tariff ineffective. Insular and continental sugar areas increased production sharply in the next few years. apparently because the high tariff made sugar a relatively attractive place to commit resources during the general depression. even though absolute prices were low. Cuban sugar exports were cut back severely. but not enough to maintain the market in the face of increasingly large insular supplies. The general effect upon the economy of Cuba was calamitous. and the situation eventually resulted in the Government of that country being overthrown in 1933. W93: In 1933. the Tariff Coulission reported that the situation was "disastrous for both Cuban and American producers.“ and reccnended to the President that the sugar supplies from all domestic and insular areas in Cuba be limited. and that duty on Cuban sugar be reduced} The sugar 111.3. Tariff Commission. a- n- , lie. 73. Washington. D.C.. Govermaent Printing Cff‘ice. l9 25 industry and the Administration were unable to reach agreement on a program that year. but in 1934 President Roosevelt sent a message to Congress asking for legislation which would achieve the following objectives: (1) To maintain the existing acreage of sugar boots and sugar cane in the Continental United States. but to limit further expansion; (2) To increase returns to domestic growers; (3) To stabilise production in the insular areas; (1+) To check the decline of imports of Cuban sugar as a means of restoring Cuba's piwer to purchase America's agricultural products. Most of the President's recomendations were contained in the Jones- Ccstigan Act. which was passed later that year as an amendment to the Agricultural Adjustment Act. WW2 Most of the general principles embodied in the original sugar legislation in 193‘! remain in effect to the present time. The present law is known as the "Sugar Act of 19148." ani it was married in 1951. 1'Source: Quoted in Bernhardt. Joshua. W W Washington. 19%. Sugar Statistics Service. Po 159- 2A more detailed discussion than found in this section is in The U. S. Su ar Pro an S or Re rts 121+. August. 1962. For even more 35-1353 amfiic treahneng of sugar legislation the reader may consult the following: Dalton. John E.. SugarI A Case Stfl in Government Control. New York: Macmillan and Company. 1937: olf. He xe, nose 3 31‘ 1011 and Its In ct on Cuba. Gas (31 e: Bernhardt. Joshua. e ar us the odor Government. 0 . cit.; Polopolus. o s. c ure er ormance o e tates Beet Su ar Indus Under oral otection ntrol. unpub shod act—orig dissertagon. UHversIfi of fififoraa, Berkeley. 1960; Turner. Jack T.. The Marketing of Sugar. New York: Richard Irwin. Ines. 1956s 26 1956. 1960 and 1961. In 1962 it was again amended and extended through 1966. The following sections will discuss the major provisions of the present legislation and modifications as they have been made since 1931}. Total Quanuty of Sugar to be Marketed he Secretary is to determine the quantity of sugar which could be marketed bring the following year. we quantity is to be such as to result in prices that are not excessive to consumers nor too low to protect the welfare of domestic producers. is a starting point. he is to consider the recent past consumption. state of current inventories. and the effects of expected changes in demand. In deter- mining the price level. the relationship between the index of prices paid by farmers and the price of raw sugars is to be taken into consider- ation. 'lhe initial detenination is made in Dacenber but can be adjusted throughout the year as changing conditions warrant. Supply Quotas for Domestic and Persia: Producing Areas The Secretary is authorised to establish supply quotas to domestic and foreign areas. the legislation has spelled out the precise foraula by which these are to be distributed. In the early years. the quotes were based on fixed percentages of the estinated con- sumption. (hem of the total consumption was then prorated according to the original shares. In the Sugar Act of 1948. this approach was changed by assigning fixed quotas to the domestic areas (Mainland Beet area. Mainland Cane area. Hawaii. Puerte Rico and the Virgin Islands). ant the Phillimnes. Host of the balance sent to Cuba except for a negligible amount. to other foreign countries. Thus. Cuba 27 received nearly all. of the consumption increases and the domestic areas were prevented from aw over-all growth. me 1952 Amendments did not change this provision. but in 1956. 55 Percent of the growth of the market in excess of 8.350.000 short tons. raw value. was allotted to domestic areas. 'lhe 1962 enactments again changed the basis. Domestic areas are now assigned a basic quota of 5.810.000 tons. plus 65 percent of requirements in excess of 9.700.000 tons. no domestic beet and mainland cane areas share such increases in proporflon to their basic quotas-«roughly on a three-fourths to one fourth basis. ‘mough Hawaii and Puerto Rico have failed to fill their quotas on occasion in recent years. a provision is included to increase their quotas if the size of future crops should visa-rant it. 1962 Amendment provided for reserves of acreage sufficient to yield 65 thousand short tons. raw value of sugar. to be committed for new boat sugar factory areas. or for expansion of existing factories. This provision represents a major departure from previous policy in regard to expansion of the boot sugar sector. In the period since the end of World War II. only four new plants for processing sugar beets have been erected in the United States. the most recent being in 1951+} At the present writing (1963). the Department of Agriculture has allo- cated acreage reserves to new processing facilities in California. Texas. North Dakota. South Dakota and Arizona for the crop years 1963 through 1965.2 In case this reserve is not utilized for new factories. 1Western Sugar Beet Producers Association. Beet Sugar Hand- M, 2nd Ediuon. San Francisco. 1961. 2Federal Register. March 5. 1963. Cgmmitment 9f Naggnal Sugar get Agreage Reserze. 1962 and Subsequent Crops. Sugar Determination 851.1. Amendment Three. 28 it is provided that it can be allocated for expansion of capacity in existing areas. Ww-The recent developents in political rela- tions between the United States and Cuba have caused some changes to be made in the latter country's quota allotments. During the previous Cuban regimes. substantially all of the United States sugar needs were provided by the domestic areas. the Phillipines and Cuba. Since the break-off of diplomatic relations between Cuba and the United States. Cuba's foner share. which was about one-third of the total quotas. has been allocated to a rather large number of friexxlly nations. The 1962 Amendments provide Cuba uith approximately 1.5 million tons. The bill further stipulates. however. that when the United States is not in diplomatic relations with a particular country the quotas are not granted. Cuba's quota thus has been designated as a so-callad l"ilebal Quota.” uhich may be filled by competitive imports from other foreign producers. mesa importations are subject to an import fee thich approximates the premium the United States price is over the world price of raw sugar. than such a premium exists. The 1962 Amendments also reduce the amount of off-shore ”direct consumption" (refined) sugar such m be imported. Prior to 1960. about 650 thousazui tens of direct consunpdon sugars entered the United States from off-shore (including domestic) producers. his amount has heenreducedtoaboutZSOthousandtons. thePhillipinesbeingtheonly ‘ non-domestic supplier with more than a negligible amount of direct consumption sugars. 29 Establishing Marketing Allotments If a domestic area should have supplies in excess of quotas. panielq selling might cause an unwarranted decline in price. In order to promote orderly marketing. the Secretary may allocate the quota among processors in each area based on past marketing history. Assignent of Proportionate Shares 1n. Secretary may also divide the quota for a domestic area among the farmers producing boots or cane. Inzis allotment. known as a l'proport:l.onate share." may be expressed in acres. tons of cane or beets. or in tons of sugar. this provision adjusts each area's pro- duction to its marketing quota and insures that each farmer's share is equitably distributed in the adjustment. the basis of the share is usually past history of production. but the Secretary is instructed to consider the interests of smaller growers and of new producers. Producers are not required to abide by the assigned share but must do so in order to receive "conditional payments.” (See below.) Other Provisions In addition to the benefits from price maintenance and stabilization. legislation insures that the growers and workers are able to share in these gains. Growers' incomes are augnented through I'conditional payments.“ which are made at a basic rate of $0.80 per ton of sugar produced. raw value. (This amounts to about $2.20 per ton of beats.) me rate decreases progressively after the first 350 short tons refined value. to a mnimum of $0.30 per 100 pounds for tonnages in excess of 30,000 tons. Receipt of these conditional pay- ments is contingent upon the grower of beets or cane (a) complying nth 30 the proportionate share restrictions. when such restrictions are in effect. (b) paying his hired workers in full and at not less than the minimmn rate (which is also set by the Secretary of Agriculture). and (c) abiding by the minimum age restrictions for juvenile workers. he program also makes provision for compensation of growers for disaster losses. Payments can be made in case of reduced yields (deficiency payments) or in case of actual loss of the crop (abandon- ' ment payments). Results of the Program No attempt will be made here at evaluation of the sugar programs. No lack of such analysis is to be noted. (See references cited on page 25. footnote 2.) the level and stability of the domestic sugar price under the sugar program has apparently achieved the stated objectives of main- taining the domestic industry. Prices to consumers have probably been somewhat higher than would have prevailed had the quota system not been in operation. As is shown in Table 2.6. the price of sugar is advanc- ing about as rapidly as is the index of prices of all foods but not as rapidly as the index of disposable consumer income. Substantial prmldums over existing world sugar prices were received by the insular cane areas of Puerto Rico- and Hawaii. the Phillipine Islands and. until recently. by Cuba. B. International Markets in Sugar umoshemco and Swerling have commented that the “gradual erosion of the 'free' market. characterized chiefly by the expansion of preferential 31 new 2.6. WHOLESALE PRICES OF SUGAR COMPARED WITH INDICE OF PRICESI OF ALL FOODS AND 01" PER CAPITA DISPOSABLE INCOME. 1935-62 : Wholesale Sugar : JPrices of : Per Capita Iear : Price Net Cash : All Feeds : Disposable Northeast : gloss“ : IBM! Cents per Pound Index Numbers. 1935-39 =- 100 1935-39 (Average) n.67 100 100 19100-111} (Average) 5.13 118 163 1945-49 (Average) 7.03 186 232 1950-51} (Average) 8.32 201 293 1955 8&2 212 323 1956 3.59 212 339 1957 3-97 213 351 1958 9-08 230 355 1959 9.14 219 370 1950 9-2“ 223 376 1961 9.21 2222 385 1962 9.372 221» 3973 2|’Source: Sugar Reports lo. 126. October. 1962. Table 19. 2January--Septmnber only. 3Jaxmary-July only. cane sugar suppliers. has been the outstanding feature of the world sugar eooncq of the hentieth Century. '1 They define the "free Ilarlcet'I as that part of international trade in sugar which enjoys no special privilege or protection in the country of destination. he United States. thich represents nearly 20 percent of the world' s consumption. has almost enurely insulated its sugar market from world economic Inmoshenko. v. 2.. Swerling. B. c.. W My... pe 325s 32 forces since 1931!. Another example of such policies is the United Kingdom vhich. through the Commomvealth Sugar Agreulent. has arranged to acquire most of her import needs at a negotiated (premium) price from Ccuonwealth sources. As a consequence of arrangements of this nature. the free sugar market represents only a fraction (of the order of 10 to 20 percent) of total world production. It supplies only residual requirements of importing countries. Prices in the free market tend to be rather unstable. his characteristic has been attributed to the low short-term elasticities of demand and supply. such that small changes in the balance of produc- tion and consumption in the residual market are associated with relatively large flucblauons in price. he narrowness era! the residual nature of the world market also are important contributing factors. flmoshenko and Swerling also point out that importing countries respond to cheaper sugar by increasing protection afforded to domestic producers. rather than by increasing consumption} he volatility in world market prices was well demonstrated in early 1963. when reduced supplies to the free world from Columnist Cuba and two years of short crops changed the supply picture such that world prices for. raw sugar skyrocketed from a 20 year low of Just above 2.0¢ per pound (P.0.B. and stowed. Greater Caribbean ports) in late January 1962. to a 1&0 year high of over 12¢ in May 1963. International Agrements in Sugar i new International Sugar Agreement was negotiated in 1953 in 1m" P0 We 33 order to cope with some of the problems of the 'free' world market. It.provided for export quotas. with the objective of’keeping prices within a target "zone” of stabilizedprices.1 The refusal of certain of the signatories to the agreement (particularly the recent Cuban regime) to abide by the export quotas has made the Agreement ineffective. 1%. e P0 3230 he stated purpose of this dissertation is to analyse the effects of changes in various technical. economic and political relationships on the prospects of the Eastern East Sugar Industry. his and the following chapter will contribute to these objectives by making an analysis of production response of sugar beats in the region. O “Production response'. or “supply response' are eoonodo terms which refer to the relationships between the total supply of a given product and the factors or forces influencing that supply. In the static theory of production. the supply relation is completely deter- mined by (a) the production functions (the relationship between resources or factors and output) for the product in question and all relevant competing products. (b) prices of the products and the capst- ing products. and (c) costs of inputs or resources. given the usual static assumptions of a profit maximising competitive firm operating under conditions of perfect knowledge} his provides a useful conceptual starting point. However. the real world situation is much more complex. and accordingly. difficult to approximate. A number of factors reduce our abiliw to measure 13.. Ready. 3. 0.. ~11... and Concepts in Supply Analysis." in Ends. II- 0.. main ode» WW hu- Iowa. Iowa State University Press. 1 . for a concise emery of the theory. 314. 35 preciser the production response for a particular consodity. Among these are uncertainty and lack of knowledge. capital rationing. non- Ionetary objectives. technical changes. fixed factors. complementary and supplementary relationships among products. and nary others. he problen of production response is of both practical and methodological interest in the case of sugar beets. is was noted earlier. the acreage of sugar beets supplied to processors in the Iastern Region has not always been sufficient to fully utilise existing plant capacity. Hence. any proposals for expansion of the industry through investment in plant facilities must demonstrate that the present production relation- ships will undergo a sufficient shift to fully employ both present and prospective capacity. Wont procedure cal-cal: upland in production response analysis is the application of statistical regression procedures to tile series data. to neasure staustically the influence of selected variables upon output. However. the facts presented in Justification of the stem' seen to rule out such an approach. these facts imply that the underlying structure being investigated is undergoing shifts. and to attupt to predict the future on the basis of historical relationships would be con-mt inappropriate} in alternative procedure is to construct a detailed static micro- economic nodel of representative farn situations. nake the necessary assumptions. Judgments and projections about factor supplies. competing 1m: type of approach was applied in Perreault. R. P.. 3:; Res nse offichianFarnersinEastCen alCoun esto gelatig moss gf Sugar Beets and Field Beans. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State Murdty. 1956.) 36 (heads. technoloy. and institutions. and determine the effect of varying prices on output and return to resources under these assumptions. his technique has been applied using budgeting procedures by Highell and Blackl and by Schuh.2 In the last decade or so. the linear programing framework using variable pricing techniques has been increasingly applied to this sort of problem. his is a mathematical technique which finds the m (or W of a particular linear function under certain specified restraints. It is possible. under certain assunptions. to represent the elenents of the static theory of the firm by a linear props-ing nodel. Solution of the nodal for given product prices deterlines the organization of resources and the amount to produce of each eo-odity which nan-ices profit. Solving for several prices of a particular product provides estimates of the optinua output of that product under each of the various prices: that is. a suppr response function.3 Wimb- sum nodal developed 1- based on projections of technoloy. product prices and resource prices for the 5—year period. 1964-1968. For convenience. the projections are referred to as for the year 1966. the center of the period. lMighell. a. L. and John D. Black. M Harvard University Press. Cambridge. Mass" 1951. 23mm. 6. 3.. The 31122;: a; a; m the Deg-gt my 3115 as W- mcmsan Amateurs max-neat Station Technical Bulletin 259. East Lansing. 195?. 3s» McKee. Dean E.. and L. n. Loftsgard. "Fragraming Intra- Farn Normative Supply Functions.‘I in Heady. E. 0.. 91:441.. eds.. t S Iowa State University Press. Anes. 1961. for a discussion of the method. 37 The order of procedure in the remainder of this chapter is as follows: (a) Some previous studies of production response in sugar beets vill be briefly reviewed. (b) The past. present and future trends in sugar beet produc- tion technology will be discussed. (c) Estimates of current resource inventories on "typical" sugar beet ferns will be presented. Chapter IV will continue the discussion of production response with a presentation of the assumptions. results and interpretation of an analysis utilizing the linear programing technique. as e s e e.-‘lhe Sugar Division of the Agricultural Stabilisation and Conservation Service. Deparhsent of Agriculture. has from tine to tine published neasurenents of responses of planted acreage of sugar beets to relative prices of sugar and all other crops. The analysis is in graphic form. and no statistical neasures are presented. However. the graphic analysis suggests fairly close relationship between sugar beet plantings. on the one hand. and the relative price of raw sugar (raw sugar price. New York. 6 nonths priortotileof sugarbeetplsnting. dividedbytheindeacofprices room-d tor W .1 ‘me work by Perreault2 for Eastern mchigan Counties is the l‘Relationships Between Sugar Prices and Sugar Beet Plantings." lOl. Septenber. 1960. Co-odity Stabilization Service. U.S. Dept. of Agriculture. washington. D.C. erreault. Roger. esu- - .5 s A- - Mic 38 only known stuw of supply response of sugar beets for the Eastern Region. Perreault. using a recursive statistical model. treated the planted acreage of sugar beets in the East Central Counties of mchigan as a function of (a) the intended acreage of field beans. (b) the price ratio of sugar beets and field beans the preceding year. (c) the price ratio of sugar beets to livestod: products the preceding year. (d) the cost of fall beet labor per year adjusted by the percentage of the acreage mechanically harvested. and (e) a damn variable representing weather conditions at planting time. lbs period under stuw was 1928- 1951}. with some years omitted. 'Ihese variables explained about 56 percent of the variation in planted acreage of sugar beets. but only the ratio of prices of beets and field beans was feund to be statis- tically significant at the 5 percent level. he analysis indicated that a 10 percent increase in the ratio of sugar beet to field bean price italices (1935-39 8 100) resulted in a 3.1 percent increase in planted acreage of sugar beets. Other variables were tested. including the yields of both sugar beets and field beans. the acreage of wheat. and the abandoment of sugar beets in the previous year. None of these were found to significantly affect the acreage of sugar beets planted. Although it was not possible to measure their effects. weather varia- tions at planting tins and uncertainties regarding labor supplies were major disturbances affecting the acreage planted to sugar beets. ' The low proportion of variation in planted acreage explained (£2 . .56) suggests that there are nary other factors. each with relatively small influence on planted acreage. Perreault hypothesizes that among these are extruaely adverse harvest weather in the previous 39 season. relative prices of crops other than beans. acreage allotments on other crops. and distance to the factory. The long period of price uncertainty before final settlement is one of a group of more subjective factors. which also includes the effectiveness of processor fieldmen in making contracts for acreage. and the unwillingness of producers to sacrifice leisure and other satisfactions for the additional income of beets when returns from other crops are at generally prosperous levels. or when opportunities for off-farm work are available. B. Technical Aspects of Sugar Beet Production in the Eastern Region m Sugar beets have but one profitable market. the beet process- ing factory. me sugar beet factory has but one profitable use. the processing of raw beets for sugar. In order to protect the investment both parties have in the crop. marketing is effected under terms of a contract between grower and processor. 'Ihe agreement makes provision for the number of acres. the conditions efdelivery. method and time of pqmsnt. and numerous other details relating to seed. advances for expenses against the proceeds of the crop. labor promenent and the like. Some of the major provisions are discussed below. (here are some variations in contract terms between compaues in the region so that all ef the following statements may not apply in specific cases.) megroweragreestodelivertotheprooessorallbeetsgrom on the acreage contracted. Upon delivery. they are weighed and tared. (To arrive at a net tonnage. the gross weight is reduced by the amount of soil or other foreign matter in the load. and by deductions for 1+0 improper removal of tops and crowns.) the processor agrees that all beets so delivered and accepted at the factory will be processed into sugar. beet pulp and molasses; such products to be sold at the compatw's discretion. The comparw agrees to pay the grower a fixed proportion (usually about 50 percent in the Eastern Region) of the 'net proceeds' from the sale of sugar. pulp and molasses. The "net proceeds“ is defined as the amount received by the compary (less ary differential received from sugar pookod in other than 100 pound bags) after deducting actual cost of out- bound freight. brokerage. taxes (including the federal processing tax of $0.535 per cwt.) and certain other specified marketing menus. The sugar per ton of beets may be determined by sampling each load. or more comonly. by the average of all sugar for each factory district. The grower receives an initial payment. usually in December. which is based on "the highest rate the company deems Justifiable." taking into consideration the expected production and returns from the sale of the products. Other payments may be made. and final settlement is usually due within 15 days after all products from that crop year are sold. or on some specified date (usually in October of the year follow- ing harvest) in the event all products are not sold by that time. me share feature of sugar beet contracts appears to be unique to this crop. me arrangement originated in the mirties when proces- sors were caught between falling sugar prices and a fixed price contract for beets. be original intention was not that the 50-50 share remain permanent. but few changes have been made since that time.1’2 J“Guam. c. 3-. Wear. M. 2An example of a typical Eastern region contract may be found in Jackson. Donald. W BBS-1+9. 0.8. Dept. of Agriculture. Washington. D.C.. March. 1962. Appendix. The primary :gisgn stem of the sugar best is the relatively large amount of sucrose stored in its roots. Sugar beets may be grown on a wide range of soils and in an equally wide range of climatic condi- tions. Actual location of prcchxction of am crop is. of course. deter- mined by the interaction of a umber of natural and economic factors such as climate. soils. topograptw. competing crop and livestock enter- prises. and cost of transportation to and extent of potential markets. Sucrose is produced in the leaf of the boot as a product of the process of photosynthesis. Most of it is subsequently stored in the beet root. he sucrose mutant of the root averages in the neighborhood of lllv to 16 percent at harvest time. High sugar content is of" consider- able importance to the processor. and thus to the grower. since a higher percentage of sugar can greatly increase the efficiency of the factory operation. Also important to the processor of beets is “purity.“ the percent of sucrose in the soluble solids of the beet. A high level of impurities reduces the proportion of available sugar in the best which can be economically extracted. A high sucrose content is typically associated with a high degree of purity so that when large quantities of sucrose are in the beet. a relatively larger proportion of that present is extracted. A number of climatic. soil and management factors are known to affect both sugar content and purity and. hence. the most economic location of sugar beet production. W.—A groving season of 150 to 200 due is required to achieve adequate beet tonnage and sugar content. Some observers indicate that the longer days in northern areas can offset 1+2 the shorter grovtlng period there. Rainfall requirements in non-irrigated areas are about 15 inches during the growing season. be critical condition for the econoslical production of sugar beets is that the environment (be it controlled or natural) is such that a relatively high level of sucrose is stored in the boot root during the last several weeks before harvest. These conditions are provided naturally where there are relatively cool. rainloss autumns. The growth of the boot is apparently inhibited by the cooler temperatures. but in the presence of adequate sunshine. sucrose will be produced and stored. Rainy. cloudy and warm weather in September and October (which are occasional hazards of beet production in Michigan and Ohio) are conducive to rapid growth of the boot. which draws off energy rather than increas- ing sucrose. In hot. arid climates. such as the Central Valley of California. sucrose storage is induced by limiting irrigation water in the late weeks before harvest of the crop. The beet seed can sprout at air temperatures near to freezing. but it does so so slowly as to produce a weakened seedling susceptible to ”damping off' or ”black root" organisms. Temperatures above '45 degrees allow a healthy emergence. After a period of conditioning. the plants become nearly as cold harcw as small grains.1 Sgfl :gmemeptsw-lhe beet survives in a wide variety of soils. Beets are most often found on soils which are deep. well-drained. and have good moisture holding capacities. On these soils high yields are lBrandes. E. W. and G. H. Coons. “Climatic Relations of Sugar Cane and Sugar Beet.“ United States Dept. of Agriculture. Iearlggok _o_f mm 19b1, Washington. D.C.. Goverment Printing Office. l9hl. 43 obtained without excessive management problems. In the Michigan and Ohio areas where irrigation is not typically practiced. the heavier mineral soils with high moisture holding capacities have an advantage over the lighter soils during periods of insufficient rainfall. Soils with properties which inhibit deep root penetration. such as high water tables. repellent soil structures or poor aeration. tend to produce beet roots of undesirable size and shape. Climate in the Study Area In the course of a discussion about difficulties with the best crop in the spring. a man with long experience in the best industry in Michigan was heard to remark. "Ibis has certainly been an unusual spring." After a moment of reflection. he added. "But all springs in Michigan are unusual.‘' me weather data in Table 3.1 are notable as much for their range as for their means . me climate in Lower Michigan and Northwestern Ohio may be characterised as being humid and continental. Rainfall averages about 30 to 35 inches annually. tith somewhat more than half occurring during the grating season. Length of the frost-free period averages around 150 days. but with considerable local variation. For example. the eastern portion of the Michigan factory districts in Sanilac. Huron and St. Clair Counties have a somethat later spring and somethat more rainfall. Most of the present growing areas are close to one of the Great lakes and so enjoy some moderating influences and longer frost- free periods. me high variation in both rainfall and temperature data which tr. shove: 1n fable 3.1 are important for the evaluation of the adaptabiliw of the beet crop to the area. Bad weather in the plant- ing or harvest seasons may delay or caplicate these field operations. TABLE 3.]. SELECTED mm PRECIPITAEON mmm STA'IIONS IN EASTERN BEE? H9811 Tom 0 ‘03.; _ .Saginaw. Michigan: Sandusky. Mich. : Findlay. Ohio Month i—Mfil 3 (ii—Hz? ) 3— (W : Range : :Range : : Range :Monthly 3 of :Monthly : of :Monthly 8 of 8 t 14.232 z : ions 8 Liana. December 27.2 21.2-34.0 26.9 22.5-32.6 30.1 20.5-42.0 lime-1" 23e5 15e7-34e2 23e3 16.7-30.4 28e5 12e6-38e6 February 23.7 12.4-30.0 24.4 19.0-31.3 29.1 18.5-38.6 mm 24.8 24.9 29.2 m 32e3 26.2-45.1 52e9 22.4-46.1 37.2 24.4-49.4 1pm 154.8 37.9-52.6 45.6 39.8-52.3 118.2 40.8-51.6 m 56.3 50.0-62.3 55.4 50.8-60.9 59.7 52.9-69.4 sauna 44.5 51.3 48.1 June 66.9 62.0-71.9 66.5 61.1—71.1 70.2 63.7-77.4 July 71.8 67.n.76.1 70.3 67.u_75.6 7M2 68.0-80.1. August 69.6 65.0-75.0 69.7 66.2-74.2 72.3 66.0-78.2 30mm 69.4 68.8 72.2 SOPtubor 6107 56e8-68e5 62e3 58.1-67.0 65e1 57e3¢71e1 October 51.1 44.1-58.2 52.4 45.9-59.8 53.7 44.9-61.8 NOV“ 37e9 29e9-u6e8 38o? 310743e3 40.4 34.7-50.2 AUTUMN 50.2 51.1 53.1 m 47.3 47.4 50.7 Excessively warn. hunid weather prior to harvest has encouraged top growth at the expense of sugar storage and provided the preconditions for infestations of the fungus disease. W leaf spot. Soils of the Study Area Soils of Lower mchigan and Northwestern Ohio are generally formed from prinary materials of glacial drifts. 1 Sugar beets have lUniversity of ascensin Agricultural Experiment Station. Baum: a... 571+. Wm June. 1960. 45 no :H: .3 8.3.8.3 Sfin $698.64 64.66 86.1364 +3.8 a $4. 34. 86 E33 $6 .86 4M6 36.84 «66 $4646 64.... 83...: QNeNs goo :NeN gerNmeO gem wheNINHeO geN “3300 844-636 $6 £6.36 86 “46.86 ~66 agnom .864 86 S6 gm $6.46 8.... 26-86 26 364.86 36 3&3 344%.“. #6 «46.26 36 86.86 Ra 42. 36.84 644 26.34 26 «66466 86 .56 $64 86 9.6 mag.“ $6.36 :6 36.86 :6 666.36 36 .3. 86.2.6 $6 2.1136 $6 36626 .36 44.34 86.6.4.6 RA «46.36 36 86.36 “64 :93. R6. 86 £6 .55: 36.. 86 86.86 $4 «3126 $4 E336 $6.36 R6 36446 R4 ““643. 34 has» 36.36 «46 $6.86 84 646.63. 34 3.2.8.6 '43. a . 5.x n 43.3. 5 n 5.x . cg » guns " owe—em " 35:02 " ownwm " 33:8“ " Hoax d “$1.565 $9.846 . 58: .30 .55 Smflofi 53:36 5334: .2395 peanut—co I H.n a 3.3.6.38»: 905m .864 64 .54. .030 8.4 $343338 33m .8846 6 .4 .8333 438.424 830 8.4 .864 .8483 tum .BOHSm .3 3 .Hmlummmawm_.wnauquomooo .saonsm uona¢93_.m.p and ooaphom nunudpz.aduaaoaz ”adm4504z you ”consom\u .Ofla § cm." .3." . and omduobd uhdv oouHJaofim \m 3 \m \m 83 4&3 «NR «\m mm? 834 64? an} .4284 .8 own )4 4434 3 Sn 4.4K 364 in» 2? N4} 4434 3% 3m .4234 .8 own nogauomaoa flag gagcoo HA a “7 proven to be especially well adapted to certain of the Hundo-Gley soils. his group of soils was formed on glacial material in the nore humid areas of the North Central region on sites that were poorly drained but not not enough for the formation of organic soils. These soils were deposited on what'uere then lake beds during the glacial periods. The Hundc-Gley soils tend to be level. fertile. well supplied with organic matter. but rather poorly drained. With the application of practices directed toward maintenance of adequate drainage and tilth. they are among the most productive of soils. In the North Central region. large bodies of such soils are found in Eastern North Dakota. Uestern Minnesota. along the Southeastern portion of the Lower Peninsula of Michigan. and in the Northwest portion of Ohio.1 The Department of Soil Science. Michigan State University. has classified Michigan soils into a number of ”Soil Management Groups." based on the properties of surface texture. slope and degree of erosion or stoniness of the soil profile to the depth of 3 to 5 feet. Soil nanage-ent groups are identified by number denoting texture (ranging firm 0 for clay to 5 for same) and the letter. a. b. c. denoting good. imperfect. or poor natural drainage.2 Eatpected yields of sugar beets and capeting crops on selected soil management groups are shoun in Table 3.2. It nust be emphasized that these yield eetlnates refer to ilproved practices (including tile drainage) by a grower who has the necessary equipment and experience and under “average" weather conditions. He irrigation is assumed. 1:14., p. 32. zCooperative Extension Service. Michigan State University. . . A _ _ , C - 3, Extension Bulletin E-159. .6056: 3.. ”8.35.3.3 02 .3353 veeceflefio .3 30.335 .350 v5 omecddnv _ fiend—”.390.“ .omednfi. vefinoaaooou assume 3953 36.9 .3505 acoaomenda den 30%.?» no 3.on pace. 5.? 098.9893 Facesuedoa oonodom Haom 05. no women one neveafium .vomvodpoqxoe ed .3fimuebfls 33m. confined: .pedpcedom 30m nodmdoaum .coevnonom .m .A no 3.9.3 one 03.3.3»de .nmma :32: .ananm god—3m :0.“ng .ooflfiom cofimnog 2.333000 .mpannepdcp 33m damaged: “condom? mm 9m 3 mm om em 2 $53 as? 33.6 Diced magmas no 358.6 3.30m Jaded £833 om\n .on 3 9n 3 mm om mm in “3%.. been as. 233 o .n .3 on ma 2. 3 om mm 3 2.33. 30.2.9: .3 due: .333” made no eleod pm .3... mm n5 om m: 03 on 8 383 8. Hood he? @2393 3.303 em 1% J_,| » 2598 acoaomgez Adam firm e 05 ngdzg AHom 93m 20 ”won—H.055 gonna” an 30.5 mama and 9am .584 am 84me 8454 gonna .N.n a 49 A8 would be expected. most sugar beets are grown on the 2c soils. The reader is urged to note the difference in expected yields of sugar beets on 2c and other soils in comparison with such differences in yields of other crops in Table 3.2. ances S Bee A considerable amount of published work on sugar beet production practices is now available.1 However. in order to set the stage for the specification of the predicted production relationships. we shall review in detail the more important aspects of technological advance. both accomplished and projected. 3911 genagemegt‘.—The size and shape of the beet can be adversely affected by improper drainage. file drain lines at 4 to 6 rod intervals in the heavy clay loam common in the Eastern Region are very effective in reducing damage from excess moisture, as well as favorably influenc- ing the umeliness which certain field operations may be performed. The analysis of Cook. m..2 in Michigan indicates that the average yield of sugar beets on tiled land exceeded that from untiled land by 3.1L tons per acre over the three seasons. 1958, 1959 and 1960. his amounts to an additional return in excess of W per acre per year. he proportion of boots grown on untiled land in the region will probably be well below 10 percent in the current (1963) season. 1'See for example U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Farmer's Bulletin No. 2060, Sugar Begt @2529 1% the North Central 3223, Washington. D.C.. GOV'te Printing Office. 19 . 3111 600k. Re Le, Je Fe Dads. and Me Ce Frakes, 0 Pr uc ac ces f c an Su a Beet e s. Michigan Agr. hp. Station Quarterly Bulletin Art. 114-38. Feb. 19 2. 2Cook. R. I... at, 5;" 1258.60 Motion fiactices 2f ficflgag SE3 Est FQOEIS. 22' gte. Table 3e 50 figagew-“Minimum tillage" as developed by Michigan State University's soil scientists has had the happy result of increasing yields while reducing the number of field operations. thus reducing costs. Yield of sugar beets was shown to decline sharply as number of tillage operations (after plowing) exceeded two.l Maw-Relatively large quantities of fertilizer are applied to the sugar beet crop. Typical recommended application rates might be in the range of 600 to 800 pounds of 5-20-10 analysis fertilizer per acre. plus additional nitrogen side dressings in amounts depending upon previous crop history and manuring applications. It has been shown that a high rate of application in nitrogen fertilizer can have detrimental effects on sugar content and purity of the sugar beet.2 The problem is complicated by an apparent effect of the level of soil moisture upon the relationship. A preliminary hypothesis by Snydera suggests that relatively warm and rainy late season weather combined with current levels of nitrogen application (at a rate of 100 to 120 pounds per acre) serves as an explanation for low sugar contents in the 1959 and 1961 seasons in the Eastern area. Relatively lighter rainfalls and cooler temperatures in 1960 and 1962 were associated with more I‘normal" sugar contents in the beat deliveries those years. which suggests that recomended levels of nitrogen 1mg. . Table 8. 28cc for example. Haddock. J. I... et. g" ”The Influence of Cultural Practices on the Quality of Sugar Beets.“ Jm 2f the mean Sages: 9f Sugar get Technologists. Vol. X. No. ll», Jan. 1959. 35mm. F. 14.. The Influence of Nitrogen Fertilization on Yield and Sucrose.“ American Society of Sugar Beet Technolo sts. 1 , x. Ea Me _V s 1963 forthcoming). 51 application should be tempered by possible large adverse effects of atypical weather conditions. 3m establishmgntw-The seed of the sugar beet is character- istically a "multigerm" form; that is. each seed ball contains several viable germs. When such a seed germinates. several seedlings sprout from each seed ball. Experience over the years has shown that the beats should be spaced approxim3tely a feet apart in the row. There- fore. hand field operations were required to bring the resulting groups of seedlings to appropriate stands. These operations are and were started when the beets were about 1+ weeks old. The first step was ”blocking" which was the removal of soil and beats from the row with a hoe. leaving beet-containing blocks at the desired interval. Then the weeds and excessive beats from this block were removed by hand and hoe. which was called ”thinning” or "singling.“ Such operations required as much as 31+ man hours per acre. in the 1946 study by Johnson and Wright.1 Ehcperimental work has been done on a number of methods to reduce the heavy work load for thinning. me first approaches were aimed at mechanical modification of the seed ball to reduce the number of germs per segment of the plant. The resulting “segnented” seed was a major advance as the improved stand often permitted the worker to operate with a long handled hoe in an erect position rather than on his hands and knees. Another approach was that of genetically modifying the seed so that it would have the one germ. his was made possible by a discovery of plants with true "monogerm" characteristics in 19148. The lJohnson. C~ En and Wright. 15- Tu W Michigan Circular Bulletin 215. Michigan Agricultural Experiment Station. East Lansing. Michigan. 191+9. 52 original stock lacked mam of the necessary qualities of yield. sucrose content. and disease resistance. so a decade of laboratory and green- house development was required before the first commercial scale plantings of a satisfactory monogerm variety were made. 11:. successful modification of the beet seed has not resulted in the complete elimination of ham! labor as had been hoped. Uncer- tainties from weather and low germination rates require the planting of several times the actual number of seeds that are needed in order to be assured of a uniform stand. The hand blocking and thinning opera- tions are thus simplified but not yet completely eliminated. Table 3.3 illustrates the trend in efficiency of labor utilization. TABLE 3.3. ACRESBLOCXED AND TEENNED PER mm PER SEASONa FOUR MICHIGAN FACTORY DISMCTS. 1955-6? ‘ 1m : W 1955 8.9 1956 8.7 1957 9.6 1958 10.1; 1959 12.5 1960 12.7 1961 14.3 1962 16.5 *Data courtesy of Michigan Sugar Company. Saginaw. tachigan. Refers to foreign national adult males only. Mechanical methods have been sought to perform these operations. and mam successful field trials have been completed. However. from 53 a farmer's viewpoint. the economics of these operations are not clear- cut. for inaccurate machine settings can result in thinning of the stand to a point which reduces yields below those achieved from hand methods. In such event. the reduced labor costs generated by the mechanical methods are quickly absorbed by reduced income.l Famers have been reluctant to adopt mechanical thinning practices in the Eastern Region. In the field survey conducted for the present study. only an insignificant minority reported am such operation in the 1960 season. The most recent approaches to the problem of establishing an optimum stand have been in the direction of improvement in planting techniques and in germination. Frskes. an present results of .1960 studies in Michigan which indicate that yield and sucrose content are not significantly different for beet spacings ranging from 50-150 beets per 100 feet of row. Precision planting of the moncgerm seed at 73* so inch intervals would result in a satisfactory stand for germination rates even below 50 percent. Precision planting equpaent has been developed which can accurately space seeds and leave the seed in an environment most conducive to germination.3 Ww-Weeds compete with beats for soil nutrients. 13.. the results reported in Davis. 1. 1n. and Metzler. w. 11.. MW. Colorado state Umv. Em. Station. Tech. Bull. 3. Fort Collins. 1958. Table 29. zFraku. main WWI.- Rastern Umted States and Canada Regional Meetings. American Society of Sugar Beet Technologists. My, East Lansing. 1961. n. R. 3.. "What's Happening to Beet Drills.“ W W. Vol. L. No. 1. 1961. Great Western Sugar Comparw. Denver. Colorado. 51+ moisture and sunshine as well as interfering in field operations. Weeds growing between the rows are controlled by the conventional cultivating techniques. Weeds within the row have been a more challenging problem. lhey have been dealt with by hand labor. first during the thinning operation. than in one. two or three hceings subsequent to this. Experi- mental work in both chemical and mechanical procedures have developed a number of increasingly successful methods} One long-time sugar beet researcher has stated. What we must do is to make the sugar beet as easy to grow as ary field crop; that is. we want to change the sugar beet from a vegetable crop to a field crop.“ Some researchers in the agronom of the sugar beet are predicting that the development of precision planting techniques and improved germina- tion which permit the beet crop to be planted to a stand. when confined with in-the-row weed control methods. have eventual praise of eliminat- ing the hand labor traditionally required in the sugar beet field. Ww-As noted earlier. the sugar beet delivered to the factory should have its leaves and crown cleanly removed. be free of dirt. stones and weeds. The crown is both relatively low in sugar and high in non-sugars; hence. improper or incomplete removal of crowns will adversely affect the rate of sugar per ton of beets which can be removed in subsequent factory operations. The “topping“ of the beet previously was done by hand laborers who followed the l'beet liftera (which loosened the boots in the ground) and pulled the plant. sliced off the crown and tops with a knife. and piled the beets for later 1Anderscn. R. N.. "Progress and Problems in Sugar Beet Weed Control." MW America-n Crystal Sugar Comparw. Vol. XVI. No. 1. l9 2. Denver. Colorado. 55 loading into trucks or wagons. The 1916 study in mchigan by Johnson and bright reported that the hand operations required 28 man hours per acre (or about 2.8 hours per ten) for pulling and topping and tho man hours per acre (or about .5 man hours per ton) for loading} these operations are now all performed by machines. Under normal conditions one man with a one-row harvester can perform the operations to place the topped beets into trucks at a rate of up to 8 to 10 tons per hour. These advances have not been entirely unlisted blessings. as machine topping. when not properly applied. can leave more tops and crane and dirt in the delivered loads than did the hand operation. Sugar content and purity in the beats that are sliced are thereby reduced. and heavy tares are charged against the delivered loads. W.nmsease control has often been a major problem with sugar beet crops. One of the most expensive cuseases in the Eastern Region is “damping-off." or "black root“ in seedlings. his is a fungus infection of the root commonly associated with cold. damp weather at the time the seeds germinate. U.S.D.A. plant breeders in Beltsville. Maryland. an). East Lansing. Michigan. are reporting promising results in breeding resistance to black root into ccmercial varieties. Also a problem. particularly in Ohio in recent years. is W leaf spot. a fungus disease of the beet which thrives in warm. humid weather. Control has been accomplished largely by breeding resistance into varieties. but significant increases in both yield and sucrose content were obtained with spray applications of oil-fungicide mixtures in 1961 and 1962 crop seasons in Ohio. laohnaon and Wright. W. 221m. 56 kgemg fog highs: yieldsw-Research efforts are being directed toward increasing yields by hydridization. Indications are that both yield and sucrose content are improved in hybrid varieties. For example. 1962 tests at East Lansing showed yields of up to 25 tons per acre and sucrose contents exceeding 1? percent. Plant breeders are confidently predicting that yield increases on the order of 10 to 15 percent over present commercial varieties will be achieved with the new mbrids. Programs are underway to develop parental lines with the necessary disease resistance and qualiw for hybrid seed production. Another promising approach in search for high yielding varieties is a relatively new technique of polyploidy. which refers to the increase (usually doubling) of the number of chromosomes in the plant by applies.- tion of certain chemicals. the resulting tetraplcid plants are some- times back-crossed with the usual diploid varieties. resulting in a triploid. The new varieties developed in these methods appear to have considerable promise. Some Michigan growers have reported strinng yield results when four rows of beets are alternated with four rows of navy beans. Research is being conducted on this developnent to determine the best row widths. spacings and fertilizer applications . ' Wan-Recent research by plant breeders has suggested that sugar beet strains canbe bred which will produce satisfactory yields of roots and percentage of sucrose and purity as compared with present comercial varieties even when harvested as much as 1+ weeks earlier. The successful conclusion of such a research program would add materially to the length of the harvest season and the processing 5? campaign. thereby greatly increasing the efficiency of utilization of capital equipment of both grower and processor. (The difficulty of storing harvested beets in the periods of warm weather in September and early October in‘the Eastern Region would limit the acreages where this innovation would be effective to that which could be processed during that period.) C. Resource Organization and Supplies eld S e - cedures and s A field survey of sugar beet growers in Michigan and Ohio was conducted in the latter part of 1961. Seventy-five Michigan growers who delivered beets to Michigan factories and three Michigan growers and 13 Ohio growers who delivered to Ohio factories were interviewed. me objective of the survey was to provide estimates relating to resource levels and organization and production practices on sugar beet farms. Sampling procedureSw-For the Michigan factory districts. the survey was coordinated with one of those conducted for a study of feed grain-livestock complex in that area.1 The population surveyed included all fame located on certain specified soil associations in the Saginaw Valley and Thumb region of Michiganywhose gross farm sales exceeded $2,500. but excluding specialty farms such as poultry. fruit and truck farms. (These excluded types are seldom found in conjunction with sugar beet growing. so this distinction proved to be of negligible consequence.) he soil associations chosen were on the lake bed soils adjacent to Lake Huron and nearly coincides mth the present boundaries of the beet 1The results of that study are reported in Lard. Curtis F., Profitable Reorganization of Representative Farms in Lower Michigan and Northeastern Indiana With Special Euphasis 9;} Feed Grain and Live- stock, unpublished Ph.D. thesis. Dept. of Ag. Econ.. Mich. State Univ.. 19 3. 58 grovdng area. The survey procedure was an area-segment type. A list of 76 townships meeting the soil and location criteria was made. new each township. two segments of two (contiguous) square miles were to be drawn at random, and all farms meeting the population specifications therein enumerated. It was determined from census data that approxi- ' mately eight townships would be required to meet the quotas of the survey. his number was insufficient to insure an adequate geographic dispersal by random drawing. Hence. the townships were ordered geographically and every ninth one selected (using a random drawing to select the starting point). It was anticipated that the number of sugar beet growers would be insufficient to meet the pro-established quota of 75 in this initial sample. Hence, a procedure was devised to fill this quote while main- taining the property of statistical independence among observations. the procedure proved necessary as the initial area-segment survey encountered but 42 operators who grew sugar beets in 1960. 'Dae additional sampling proceeded as follows: a list of farmers who were sugar beet growers for the 1960 crop year was obtained from the Michigan office of the Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service.1 A list of growers comprising every twentieth grower on the A303 roster was obtained. Addresses of these growers were found and the list was ordered geographically. Using a random starting point. the growers were then contacted in this order until the quota was filled. In Ohio factory districts the procedure followed was identical to that used to fill the Michigan 1m assistance of Edward Lunde and his staff is acknowledged. 59 quota except that the sugar companies provided the list of growers.l Qggtas by gimp-In order to obtain a sufficiently large sample for each size group in the Michigan districts. a quota system for each such group was instituted. Sampling was random with the size of farm variable during the first portion of the survey. From these first l+2 schedules it was estimated that the distribution of farms in the popula- tion under study by size was as follows: Small (120 acres or less) 38 percent Medium (121-180 acres) 36 percent Large (181 or more acres) 26 percent The quota for each size group was set at 25. However. an error was made in keeping the survey records so that when the final nmbers of farms were tabulated. the precise quotas of 25 observations in each size category were not met. No attempt was made to sample by size in the Ohio districts. Questionnaire and Interviewing Procedure he survey questionnaire was quite extensive. so it will not be reproduced here .2 It included questions of the following general types: ‘ (a) resources-detailed answers regarding quantity and quality of physical and financial resources were obtained. including quantity and value of land. machinery and equipment. buildings and livestock. llorthern Ohio Sugar Compem. Fremont and Findlay. Ohio. and Buckeye Sugars. Inc.. Ottawa. Ohio. 2See Lard. Curtis F.. Mt" Appendix C. for a sample questionnaire. 6O livestock facilities. liquid capital in the fem of cash or crop inventories. net worth. and operator. family and hired labor. (b) production practices and input-output relationships-- these questions dealt with the amounts of inputs. such as fertilizers and sprays. technology of input combina- tion. such as loose housing-parlor or stanchion type dairy operations. and certain production measurements per unit of input. such as crop yield per acre. rate of gain. and milk production per cow. (c) resource demand and supply relations-mother questions were devoted to obtaining estimates relating to supplies and prices of inputs when such information would not be generally available elsewhere. Examples of such resources are credit from noninstitutional sources (such as family or neighbors) and land avail- able for sale or for rent in the farmer‘s immediate neighborhood. Some questions were also related to the off-farm Job opportunities for operator and family labor and of the potential supply of such labor to the nonfarm econow. W.—1he interviews for the Michigan factory districts were conducted in the summer of 1961. In order to have a complete crop year's data. the production figures obtained pertain to the 1960 crop year. and resource inventories were as of December 31. 1960. me Ohio area was surveyed in November 1961. Data taken were thus for the 1961 crop year and resource inventories as of the date of the survey. Survey Results The emmerated farms were classified into three size categories and three type categories. The type-of-farm classification was based on the I'maJor enterprise" as measured by comparison of gross sales. be major enterprise types encountered were dairy. livestock (hogs and/ or beef cattle) and field crops. The three sizes of farms were (1) 120 acres or less. (2) 121 to 180 acres. and (3) 181 or more acres. which 61 will be termed ”small." “medium.“ and I'large'I for convenience. The distribution of farms and resulting classification is presented in Table 3.1}. In both areas. sugar beet farmers were mostly in the field crop category-.85 percent in Michigan and 68 percent in Ohio. The balance. however. have a tendency to be livestock farmers in Ohio and to be dairy farmers in Michigan. The most striking difference between the areas seems to be the acres of land operated in the farm units. Nearly 90 percent of the Ohio farms fall into the 'large" classification of over 180 acres. as compared to 26 percent reported for the Michigan sample. Important differences were also noted in the cropping programs and enterprise organization in the two areas. As illustrated in Table 3.5. in the Michigan districts the major competing crop is seen to be dry edible beans (usually the small white or pea bean). Farming in the Ohio districts might be typified as "Corn Belt" in variety. All farms reported corn and soybeans. and may had some sort of hog or beef production enterprise. TABLE 3.“. CLASSIFICATION OF SURVEY FARMS BY SIZE AND TYPE : e C x ' es ° * a ea Small (120 acres or less) 21+ it 1 29 Medium (la-180 acres) 2]. l O 22 Large (181 acres or more) 19 2 3 2!} Total 6n 7 a 75 Ohig 3” Small (120 aiegss or 1388) O 0 g g Hedi a s 2 O Larg‘em(£8lz.]:cres ggmore) 9 1 1+ 14 Total 11 1 it 16 *Note that the size distribution given here is non-random. due to the sampling quotas used for fun size. hrors in field survey records resulted in the size groups failing to meet the quotas of 25 in each group. See text for discussion. 62 .n.o 55 awed-m .3333 one econ oodmfluoo no.“ Spam «no.8 .5338 you 33483 nae neon £939 .930 moesaosHm .aepmoum edema took .39” hp voafion mesa noosHocHh 63.38.50 05 no omeonos has gnome.» cedaeodfieneao 9.2.3 a.“ mans“ men???» He sense: 3 women nomoflsousm a.“ 235.2} 83 23 3 Rd 33 $3 _ $3 3.3 Added ed p m cu m 3 mm 3 0 mm mm 2.... n3 3 made one .3. as 33 so as as vb. as. as as 133 E s we m 3 am e R 3 mu :3 3 on 386 a E as as as :3 me as as as 33 so u S m m mm mm D 8 r: we do as.6 33a 3 3 83 8; Rd 83 83 Rd 83 Amend as n mm «H .3 mm 0 mm 8 me an 8H 3H d0.6 39E .33 2: 8V 3 2.3 A3 A8 33 Rd 38 $2.5 .3 N e m 3 a o is 2 mm . 3H 3 8H 8.6 3.5 53.2 2: Ge 5 $3 38 vb as 2.3 33 Windham :3 o s N m S e mm m 3 mm. in 3 do u 39E 33.6 3 o o 6 «gig . ”spasm” gauge—om“ e085 odeH. imam. eaofim :Hassm seen?” them. he a shoe «homemade? used one.” 3. 31.616on 659 ,u ”.33. i a, ”3.6” .86. .86. 5335838 0..... mmoflo Hm Eh am 9534 @454 «gm Eon 20 mm: Q23 .m.m a 63 Four "typical farm situations“ were selected for further analysis on the basis of the distributions reported in the survey. For the Michi- gan districts. dairy and livestock farms did not represent a sufficient proportion of the population to warrant further analysis. Hence. the three sizes of "Field Crop" farms were designated as representative of the Michigan districts. All the useable interviews for the Ohio districts were grouped to form a representative fare situation. The representative farm situations were defined in terms of the lean resource endovnents of each category. as shown in Table 3.6. W mw-New technologies and more intensive resource use will no doubt continue to aid the trend toward larger yields per acre of beets. However. the nest important potential source of increased output of sugar beets in the Eastern Region is from the additional comihent of land. Additional land resources which are well adapted for sugar beets can cone from two sources. given the number of farms. he proportion of a given fan's cropland devoted to sugar beets may increase. or the pro- portion of farmers growing beets can increase. The results of the field survey indicate that the proportion of cropland on sugar beet farms actually devoted to sugar beets was 16.2 percent (about one sixth) in the Michigan districts and 12.5 percent (about one eighth) in Ohio. me proportion of farms located on the appropriate soils is a little more ditficult to ascertain. he estinates free field survey work done by on. State Universityl and from the 1959 Census of Agriculture indicate lire: field survey data provided by Dr. Francis Walker. Depart- ment of Agricultural Economics. Ohio State University. personal communica- tion. October 30. 1962. 64 TABLE 3.6. RESOURCES ON REPRESENTATIVE FARM SITUATIONS W ° Ohio : . Michigan Districts ; Dis; acts :Units: Small . Medium : Large : All : : Field : Field : Field : Ohio .- = W (24 farms 21 farms l9 farms Land: Tetal land operated Acres 86 155 271 295 Cropland operated ' 75 140 246 276 Cropland owned " 61 100 146 91 Cropland rented “ 14 40 100 185 Labor: Operator labor Man equiv. 1.00 1.03 1.40 1.08 Deadly labor " .30 .32 .48 .24 Age of operator Years 46 46 42 42 Education of oper. “ 7.5 8.7 9.3 10.9 Crop.Machinery: Tractors ownedp- (2 a. 3 plow) Number 1.80 1.95 2.00 1.55 Tractors owned»- (4'& 5 plow) " .38 0.48 1.47 1.18 8 ar beet harvester-- one row) “ .13 0.42 0.75 .25 5 ar beet harvester-- “fitwo row) " .09 0.05 0.15 .06 Trucks (1.5 tons or lager) I. 055 096 1050 .88 Livestock & Equipment: Dairy cows Head (cow) 1 1 6 2 Milking capacity ' 2 2 8 2 Fhrrouing capacity Head (sow) 3 3 2 3 Hog feeding Head (feed. °8P8¢19Y P183) 15 18 20 33 Beef steer feed.cap. An. units 5 12 17 37 Silo capacity Thus 7 32 50 73 Financial: Real estate assets $1,000 46.7 51.1 78.7 50.8 Chattel assets (mach. & livestock) " 7.2 7.7 17.7 14.2 Liquid assets " 3.2 5.4 10.6 13.2 flotal assets " 57.1 64.2 107.0 78.2 1131311112168, real OStO II 4.0 509 1301 205 Liabilities, mach. & livestock " 0.5 0.5 1.7 1.9 Liabilities, other ” 0.1 0.3 0.8 2.5 Tbtal liabilities " 4.6 6.7 15.5 6.9 Net “firth II 52.5 5705 9105 7103 65 that less than 5 percent of the farms in sugar beet producing counties in Northwest Ohio are sugar beet growers. It appears that there are ample adapted soil resources in the Ohio districts. and expansion in this area is but an economic matter of bidding this land away from alternative uses. In the Michigan districts. the field survey of the Saginaw Valley-Thumb cash-cropping region by Lard encountered 42 farms (out of 100 farmers interviewed) who were beet growers} m. 1959 Census of Agriculture reported 2.425 beet farmers out of 7.610 Class I through Class V fans (or 32 percent) in the four main Michigan sugar beet producing counties (Bay. Saginae. Tuscola. Huron). this is regarded as being consistent ulth the survey estimate of 40 percent of farmers on the better quality lake bed soils being beet farmers. since there are large areas in each of these counties which are on the lighter textured. saw soils. In terms 2E1 of this rough physical inventory of adapted soils. there is no reason why substantially more acreages of beets could not be grain in either the mchigan or mic districts. Later analysis will show that other factors in addition to soil resources are important in the choice of ubether or not sugar beets are included in the crop rota» tion. Elana-The relatively heavy labor requirements and their seasonal distribution continue to be ranked among the major problems in the sugar beet industry. mu: the harvest period effectively mechanized, the main 1M. Ce Fe. Me 66 focus of attention is on the Spring labor requirements for stand reduc- tion and weed control. mese operations. particularly thinning. must be performed within a relatively short period for maximum effectiveness. The thinning operation usually begins some 4 weeks after planting. in middle or late May, and the [weed hoeing extends into July. This period is one of heavy labor demands on the operator's time and management capacity from other enterprises. Planting and weed control operations must be carried out in the corn. soybean and dry bean crops. Furthermore, the man hours required to cover an acre are quite large. Even the "hoe trimming" operation. which is replacing "blocking and thinning" in fields planted with monogerm seed. requires up to 11 hours. and the hoeings require some 5 hours per acre. Even though this is a major improvement from the 30 or more hours reported by Johnson and Wright.1 when the present-day larger acreages are involved it is still more labor than most families have available. The heavy seasonal requirements have been met by the importation of migrant field workers. mese workers are mostly domestic in origin. although in previous years there have been some Mexican National workers imported. ‘Ihe beet sugar companies usually undertake the responsibility for recrxdtment and allocation of the workers. Some of the expenses. such as housing. are charged to the grower. but the comparw typically bears the cost of recruitment and much of the cost or transportation of the migrants (usually from Texas). bus. the processor. too. has a real interest in the reducfion of spring labor requirements. lJohnson and wright, 1139ng $333 Beet Costs. Mio- p. 16. 67 The introduction and adoption of monogerm seed and the other techniques discussed earlier in this chapter have had a marked effect upon the demand for labor. One measure of these effects is the "acres blocked and thinned per worker" presented in Table 3.3. Most of the benefits of this increased efficiency have been conferred on the worker through increased wage rates. It has been the policy of at least one compam not to change the contract rate per acre in their district. he workers absorb all benefits in this case. The minimum wage rates for field workers specified by the Department of Agriculture for 1963 under the Sugar Act. provisions are $1.05 per hour. up from $0.95 in 1962.1 There have been some indications at this writing (June. 1963) that the agreemnt with Mexico regarding the importation of field workers from that country might be discontinued. In such event. the effects on supply and cost of migrant field labor for Eastern beet growers are difficult to assess. here will be no direct effect. since the Mexican National workers are not now important (none in Michigan beet fields in 1963). However. the removal of this source of supply of labor may have some influence on the availability of and wage rate for the ruaining pool of domestic migrant workers. W.ume net worth of sugar beet growers reported in Table 3.6 indicates that the typical farm situation does not suffer from a shortage of capital. Most of the capital is tied up in real 1W reprinted from Federal Beam:- or April 24. l 3. For a more general discussion of farm labor. see Elterich. J .. M" Persmcgve on fichigg's Fm Lam; grows. Agricultural Ecperiment Station. Michigan State University. East Lansing. Michigan. 1963. 68 estate. The typical farmer had very small liabilities in proportion to his assets. Lending agencies are willing to provide much.more credit than the farmer appears to wish to obtain. In addition. the processing companies typically provide both credit (as well as a number of other services) to growers under contract. The grower can.have a number of his operations such as thinning and hoeing labor and contract harvesting and hauling paid for and charged against the crop. The amounts plus interest are deducted from the first crop payment. The results of fitting Cobb-Douglas equations to income and expense data for sugar beet growers suggest that the average grower could well afford to transfer capital from real estate into cash expenditures. Lard reports that.Michigan cash crop (including sugar beet) growers earned an average of $2.60 for every dollar of cash expenses in 1960.1 This provides a return per dollar substantially above the cost of borrowing at 5.5 percent for real estate mortgage or 7 percent for chattel mortgage. llard. Curtis r.. Michigan State University. unpublished data. CHAPTER IV SUGAR BEET PRODUCTION RESPONSE II - TEE ANALYTICAL MODEL A. Static Model of Production Response in Sugar Beets The discussion of the previous chapter has covered the technical relationships of Eastern Region sugar beet production and some aspects of the present organization and supplies of resources. The former provide the basis for projecting a production relation for sugar beets. The latter allowed us to specify representative farm situations for the subsequent analysis. In this section. the assumptions and specifications of the linear programming model will be discussed in some detail. This will entail the prediction of both resource and product prices for beets and the relevant competing crops. as well as technical produc- tion relationships for all of these. Such projections necessarily involve us in a multiplicity of hazards and possible errors. Primarily. of course. there is the problem of accurately predicting prices and production techniques for a future period. Furthermore. in order to simplify the problem to manageable proportions. we assume that one set of input-output relationships. one set of product and resource prices. and but a few sets of resource organizations will adequately portray the situation for a region. We thereby ignore a cluster of problems; in particular. intra-regional soil and climate variability. the effects of scale of operation on resource use and 69 7O costs. differences in the goals and capabilities of managers. and behavior in the face of imperfect knowledge. However. with full recognition of these limitations of the analysis. we shall proceed. for such restrictions on realism are necessary in order to reduce the problem to a manageable scope. After the static analysis is presented. some of the more obvious limitations will be discussed. programming model may be applied to problems relating to the optimal organisation of the resources of the firm operating under a free price system. In this interpretation. usually called I'activity analysis." we visualize an entrepreneur who has at his disposal fixed amounts of a number of different resources. These resources can be combined to produce varied quantities of several different products. It is known how much of the 1th resource is required to produce a unit of the 1th product. and how much profit is made for each unit of each product. If such a problem can be expressed in the linear programming framework. then a solution in terms of the optimal quantities produced of each of the 2 products can be found which fill maximise profits. be major elements of a linear programing problem include : (l) a linear function 31:]. + 32x2 +eeee+ on?» to be amused subject to a set of restrictions given in (2) and (3) below. This function is called the 71 “objective" or "criterion“ function. Coefficients of the a“ variable of this function in the activity analysis interpretation are 'net revenues" or 'net profits“ to a unit of output of the 2‘11 product. (2) a set of linear equations which give the total amount of the 1th resource to be used ‘11”‘1 " ‘12‘2 *m” Hair: The a1 j are called “input-output" coefficients. since they represent the number of units of the 1th resource needed to product a unit of product j. (3) the total use of the ith resource must not exceed the amount available. so we have a linear inequality in the form: ‘ ‘ 811:1 4' aizxz +eeee+ linxn- bi me b1 represents the amount of the 1th resource on hand-:nd are usually called "restrictions.“ To achieve precise results from the application of linear programming. the problem under stuw must meet or approximate the assumptions of the mathematic model. These assumptions are as follows:1 1. Additivity and linearity of activities or processes. 2. Invisibility of processes and resources. 3. . limited resources. lfieadw. E. 0. mi Candler. w.. W Iowa State Univ. Press. Ames. Iowa. 1959. P. 17. 72 4. Production.taking place inla finite number of alternative processes. 5. Single-valued expectations (that is. resource supplies. input-output coefficients and prices are known with certainty). In.order to express a problem in the activity analysis frame- work. it must also be assumed that the entrepreneur maximizes a profit function which can be expressed.in a linear form. None of these assumptions are precisely met in most activity analysis applications. including the present problem. Of particular concern are the assump- tions of the single-valued.expectations and the linearity and additivity of the activities. However. it should be noted that any alternative microeconemic approach. such as budgeting. suffers from similar dif- ficulties and.is much more limited in the range of alternatives and the degree of complexity which can be undertaken in a reasonable length of time. The adaptability of the linear programming routine to a solu- tion on a high-speed computer greatly simplifies the search for a solun tion to a complex problem. Furthermore. a model can be modified in a number of ways to more nearly approach the conditions of the particular problem under study. For example. additional activities can be added to approximate segments of a nonlinear relationship. or behavioral responses to imperfect knowledge or risk can sometimes be handled by special restrictions on resource use. Such modifications are made. however. at a definite cost in additional complexity and computing. The model of a representative sugar beet farm constructed for this problem was rather large and complex. The final system of equations 73 included 72 equations (resource restrictions) in 121 variables (activities). The large number of activities can be attributed mainly to certain methodological considerations. The definition of a fixed asset proposed by G. L. Johnsonl suggests that resources are fixed endogenously at levels where the MVP of the resource falls between its acquisition and salvage prices. In order to incorporate this concept into a linear programing framework. one or more acquisition and salvage activities were incorporated into the model for each of a large number of resource categories. The methodological import of the model will be reported elsewhere. The present discus- sion is confined to the implications of this solution for supplies and the future competitive position of the sugar beet enterprise on the farms of the Eastern Region. Enpirical Specification of the Model Enpirical data assembled for the linear programing problem included: (a) technical input-output coefficients (b) net revenue coefficients for the objective function (e) resource restrictions. ec s s .uInput-output coefficients were developed through a ”synthetic" procedure. Survey results were combined with experience and judgment of specialists from the Depart- ments of Farm Crops. Soil Science. Agricultural Engineering. Animal 1See for example. Johnson. G. 1... "Supply thctions--Some Facts and Notions.” in Heady. E. 0.. M... a s W “W Ames. Iowa. Iowa State College Press. 1958. p. 74. 74 Husbandry. Dairy. and Agricultmral Economics of Michigan State University. as well as from representatives from the sugar industry. Judgments were obtained as to expected production techniques and levels of various inputs and outputs for the future periods under consideration. From-these recomendations a “table of operations and inputs“ was constructed for each crop enterprise. (These tables are included as appendix tables 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8 and 9 in Appendix II.) Data for livestock production and equipment and for machinery were obtained from a wide variety of published and unpublished sources.:L MW.—The first step in this procedure was to estimate expected input and product prices. These were determined on the basis of recent past trends and relationships. taking into account Government programs where relevant. Input .‘ costs were based on 1961 data. projected on the basis of recently observed trends. (For examle. fertilizer and seed prices were not assumed to change from the 1961 levels. while cost of items such as land. machinery and building materials were projected to 1966 using relevant U.S. Government or specially constructed indices.) The net revenue budgets reproduced in Table 4.1 were then derived from prices and the previously mentioned input tables. W.ulhese were derived from the field 1m of these references are listed in sinion. a. 1.. Some '11:! e: S c s e- S or =--: e 1 . '1" N Fangs; States. 1%.-52. Research Report No. 35. Agr. Econ. Dept.. Univ. of 111.. 19 O. and mnton. R. A.. W Ca . .. f '1‘9 - tand - nt Res. Report No. 34, Agr. Econ. Dept.. Univ. of 111.. 1960. 75 survey data as reported earlier. Survey results and secondary data were used to specify technical and institutional restrictions on resource use. (Examples of each of the latter two types of restraints are the manmum proportions of the cropland in intertilled crops and in the amount of wheat allotment.) The actual model used in the analysis will not be presented in its entirety from lack of space.1 We will. however. discuss some of the empirical assumptions of the model and present some of the more important net revenue budgets an). the input-output coefficients which were developed in the course of the analysis. Crop Activities and Restrictions See Tables 4.1 and 4.2 for assumptions as to inputs and costs and rebirns for crop enterprises. Appendix Tables 3 through 9 show the explicit technical assumptions. mw-Maximm acreage of intertiJled row crops was assumed to be 75 pOrcent of the available cropland. W.--Sugar boots were projected to yield 18 tons per acre in 1966 and to return $12.85 per ton (yield net after tare; return including Goverment payments of $2.20 per ton). The yield assumption is a projection of the post-war trend. (Introduction of twbrid varieties on a large scale would make this projection too conservative.) Acres 1"For readers interested in the technical aspects of the problem. a model substantially equivalent to the one employed here and constructed cooperatively with this one is presented and described in Lard. M. TABLE 4.1. 76 1966 PROJECTED COSTS AND RETURNS PER ACRE TO SUGAR EEEJS AND COMPETING CROPS. MICHIGAN AND OHIO DISTRICTS. HEdible Corn : Corn : Michigan Dist;;cts : Al- Item : Sugar : Dry: for : for : Oats : Wheat :falfa : Beets : Beans:Grain:Silage: ° : Hay INCOME Yield per acre 18T l8cwt 100bu 18T 80bu 55bu 3.0T Price per unit $ 12.85* 6.00 1.04 6.50 0.65 1.78 18.00 Gross income 231.30 108.00 104.00 117.00 52.00 97.90 54.00 VARIABLE CASH EXPENSES $ $ $ $ $ $ $ Seed 1.50 2.45 2.40 2.40 3.74 4.83 1.86 Fertilizer 25.20 6.30 13.65 13.65 7.82 15.45 7.02 Other materials (sprays. etc.) 7.00 1.50 1.00 1.00 0.50 --- ---- Machinery (pro-harvest) 2.49 2.49 2.81 2.81 2.09 1.04 ---- Machinery' harvest) 6.45 1.58 2.98 1.80 0.63 0.63 3.73 Hauling (truck or wag.) 3.80 0.37 1.17 2.95 0.71 0.53 0.37 Beet labor 13.50 ---- ---- --- --- --- ---- Other 1.75 ---- 5.00 --- --- --- ---- Sub-total variable cash expenses 61.69 14.69 29.01 24.61 15.69 22.58 14.03 Return over variable cash expenses 169.61 93.31 74.99 92.39 36.31 75.32 39.97 OVERHEAD COSTS Cash enses Machinery (dep.. etc.) 31.16 12.34 10.72 12.16 9.60 7.67 16.45 Miscellaneous (phone. travel. etc.) 8.42 4.08 3.84 4.08 1.84 3.60 2.00 Real estate taxes 5-75 5.75 5.75 5-75 5-75 5-75 5-75 Sub-total cash overhead 45.33 22.17 20.31 21.89 17.19 17.02 24.20 Total cash expenses 107.02 36.86 49.32 46.50 32.88 39.60 40.65 Return over all cash expenses 124.28 71.13 54.68 70.50 19.12 58.30 15.77 CHARGES FOR LAND INVESTMENT.AND OPERATOR & FAMILY LABOR Land charges 8 5. 576 31.63 31.63 31.63 31.63 31.63 31.63 31.63 Labor charges @ 2. 00/hr. 25.50 16.00 11.30 21.20 6.80 4.80 15.70 Sub-total 57.13 47.63 42.93 52.83 38.43 35.43 37.33 TOTAL CHARGES 164.15 84.49 92.25 109.33 71.31 75.03 77.98 RETURN TO RISK AND humanism 67.15 23.51 11.75 17.67(-19.31) 22.87(-23.98) *Price for sugar beets includes government payments. 77 TABLE 4.1. Continued : Ohio Districts (where different; Item : Corn ' Corn : : : _ . for : for : Oats :Soybeans: Wheat : grain : Silage : : : INCOME Yield per acre 110 bu 19.5 T 70 bu 37 bu 45 bu Price per unit $ 1.04 6.50 0.65 2.25 1.84 Gross income $ 114.40 126.75 45.50 83.25 82.80 mum CASH EXPENSES $ $ $ $ :3 Seed 2.40 2.40 3.94 3.50 4.83 Fertilizer 14.80 14.80 7.82 7.12 14.15 Other materials (sprays. etc.) 1.00 1.00 0.50 ---- --- Machinery (pre-harvest) 2.81 2.81 2.09 ‘3.35 1.79 Machinery (harvest) 3.17 1.90 0.63 1.40 0.63 Hauling (truck or wagon) 1.29 3.22 0.59 0.40 0.45 Beet labor --- -- --- --- ---- Other 5 . 50 an an an ..-- Sub-total variable cash expenses 30.97 26.13 15.57 15.72 21.85 Return over variable cash expenses 83.43 100.82 29.93 67.53 60.95 OVERHEAD COSTS Cash enses Machinery (depreciation. etc.) 10.85 12.87 9.55 11.82 7.53 Miscellaneous (phone. travel. etc.) 3.96 4.35 1.62 2.95 2.90 Real estate taxes 4.95 4.95 4.95 4.95 4.95 Sub-total cash overhead 19.76 22.17 16.12 19.72 15.38 Total cash expenses 50.73 48.30 31.69 35.44 34.23 Return over all cash expenses 63.67 68.70 13.81 47.81 45.57 CHARGES FOR LAND INVESTMENT AND OPERATOR AND FAMILY LABOR Land charges (0 5.5%) 27.28 27.28 27.28 27.28 27.28 Labor charges (0 2.00/hr.) 11.60 22.60 6.70 9.30 4.80 Sub-total 38.88 49.88 33.98 36.58 32.08 TOTAL CHARGES 89.61 98.18 65.67 72.02 69.31 RETURN TO RISK AND mmemmm 24.79 28.57 {-20.17) 11.23 13.49 78 .mpoop no wcfioo: use mcacnasp new vegan yonwa psmAMdE_movdflmwv undo: honed .mpoon ueMdm new; os.m ms.s mm.m om.HH om.n mm.a os.~ os.m oe.oa me.m oo.m .na.ma .aas asscaeeasce . use .8an 93.280 oa.o mn.a oe.a om.n mo.m 0 ea. oe.a oa.m mm.m om.a om.m eases Assam my R3095 m~.H oo.~ OH.H om.m oa.m mm.s mm.H mH.H om.m ca.m om.m 0H.N eases Assam NV noposya mm on em mm mm om om om on on em om .ha cum on em oh so we om om or om om or ems .ha moma om om om we we 0 om om on on as ow .sa 2 acefiaasaea moa on ma NH NH m moa ma NH NH mm m.H .ha seem pmog3umcmon» made ”o «H macaw “ mm "960:3“ mpmo no sawmnmmwgowmmwom "mpoomu « ”them A u how “new ”smash“ “ a new a new a hug “Admamu " o GoHO o o 0 I o O 0 tags. 83H . u u o .nhoo . add . . . choc « Shoo.oanadm. . . « mmwaupmda dmmwnowz « mme CH zOHHothmm .mBoHMHmHD OHmo 92¢ z¢UHmoHE .mmomu UZHBmmzco az< memmm depmnmmo< mam mBDAZandonwmm Omaofiqmm .N.# mqmga 79 in the sugar beet crop were limited to that previously contracted. which typically was about one sixth of the available cropland based on the farm survey data. It was assumed that moncgerm seed would be used as well as one pro-emergent spraying for weeds. Migrant labor was assumed to be hired for one “hoe-trim” thinning and one used hoe- ing. All other labor was assumed to be performed by the operator and family or by hiring of seasonal labor where necessary. Hauling costs were estimated on the basis of eight miles. W.nne "pea“ or 'navy" bean is the most important crop competing with sugar beets in the Michigan districts in terms of both acreage and net returns. A goverment price support program of the loan-purchase agreement type has been in effect in recent years. he basic support rate is from $6.40 to $6.90 per curt. for the 1963 crop. New varieties are expected to contribute to the improvement of. both been yields and quality in future years. The dry bean crop uas projected to yield 18 cut. per acre at a price of $6 per out. Labor requirements for hand hoeing and chopping make this crop second only to beets as ,a heavy user of labor. but most farms utilise only fanih' labor for these tasks in contrast to the practices for sugar beets. The acreage restriction for dry beans in the model was 50 percent of cropland. mw-In the Ohio districts. soybeans are in the rotation rather than dry beans. although corn is a more attractive alternative there under the projected price and yield relationships. Soybeans are restricted to 50 percent of the cropland in the model. The projections were for a 37 bushel per acre yield at a price of $2.25 per bushel. 80 Mw-Crop acreage of wheat was limited to that of the allot- ment level as reported in the farm field surveys. It was assumed that the type of support program in effect in 1963 would continue to be in effect during the projected period. (This assumption may prove to be erroneous.) The soft white winter wheat most commonly grown in Michigan was projected to yield 55 bushels on the sugar beet soils and return $1.78 per bushel. The soft red winter wheat of the Ohio area was pro- jected to yield 45 bushels and return $1.84 per bushel. 'ngw-Corn acreage was restricted to 50 percent of the cropland. Iields were projected to 100 bushels in mchigan and 110 in Ohio. The continuation of an acreage diversion program of the form in operation in 1962 was assumed. However. representation of the various alternatives in the model was difficult and expensive in terms of additional equations. It was therefore assumed that the operator would not comply with this .type of diversion program. Net price to the farmer for shelled corn was projected to be $1.04. glam-Oats represented all small grains (oats. barley. buck- wheat and rye) in the model. Acreage was restricted to 50 percent of the cropland. Price was projected to $.65 per bushel. while yields were «mated at 80 bushels for Michigan and 70 bushels per acre for the One districts. Ww-No liadt was set on acreage of rotation meadow. Such meadow is assumed to yield 3 tons of hay per acre on the basis of 3 cuttings per season. Net price for baled hay was projected to be $18 per ton. 81 Livestcck Activities gade A mam-Production per cow for the dairy activities was projected to be 11,500 pounds (3.5 percent butterfat) of 1.111: to sell at a price of $4.22 per hundredweight. To the total milk income of $485.30 is added $71.72 of sales of cull cows and calves for a gross income of $557.02. Cash expenses (marketing. protein supplement. veterinary. etc.) were estimated at $88.97 per cow. leaving a net return to farm produced feed. equipment. labor. management and risk of $468.05 per cow. (Replacement heifers and calves were assumed to be a total of 0.90 head per mature cow. Feed inputs per cow (plus replacements ) were: corn equivalents. 38 hundredweight; hay. 3.28 tons; corn silage. 5.40 tons: pasture (in hay equivalents). 2.77 tons; soybean oil meal (40 percent). 5.75 hundredweight. Dairying was of minor importance in the representative farms . which were all of the Field Crop type. It was therefore assumed that any investment in additional dairy capacity would be in a parlor-loose housing system. Estimates of labor use were based on work at the University of Minnesota} Estimated labor requirements were 62.81 hours per cow (again including replacements) for the herringbone parlor system selected. Provision was made for increasing the capacity of farms for dairy production by investment in additional cows. housing. milking parlor and equipment capacity. 13ee references in Hinton. S S cted c 8 WW Mi- 82 Ww-A number of different techniques and methods were represented in the beef feeding acflvities. Two basic systems were used: 700 pound yearlings on feed for 180 days and 430 pound calves on feed for 360 days. For each basic system. alternatives using local dairy breed steers and alternatives using beef-type steers were included. For each of these classes. several types of feeding programs were considered. such as all silage for roughage; all hay for roughage; and pasture and hay or silage for roughage. Finally. an alternative utilizing mechanical feed handling with low labor require- ments was available for certain of the drylot beef steer activities. The twice-a-year system utilizing yearling steers which was selected as the most profitable alternative by the program will be described as an illustrative example. nose steers were assumed to gain 2.0 pounds per day for a total of 360 pounds in the 180 days. Their ration consisted of 21.5 hundredweights of corn equivalents. 0.21 tons of hay equivalents and 160 pounds of protein supplement (40 percent). Labor requirements. on the basis of lOO-head lots. were estimated at 5.3 hours per head. The steers were assumed to weigh 700 pounds and cost $23.75 per cwt. delivered to the farm. They were sold at 1.060 pounds at $23.50 per cwt. after transportation and marketing costs. The model also included activities to represent acquisition of additional housing and feeding capacity for steers. W.—Hog production alternatives were of three classes: confinement farrowing and feeding. confinement farrowing with portable Qpasture) feeding. and portable farrowing and feeding. 'me 83 subsequent analysis showed the land to be too valuable in crops in these areas for the pasture alternative. the confinement system allowed for farrowing in each quarter of the year. It was assumed that a sow would have one litter of eight pigs. the sow. weighing #00 pounds. would then be sold some time after the pigs were weaned. with one gilt from the litter saved as a replacement. 'me pigs were assumed to be grown out and sold at 215 pounds 180 days after farrodng. Feed requirements for sow and litter up to the time of sale were: 61.7 hundredweight of corn equivalents and 12.3 hundredweight of soybean oil meal (40 percent). Labor requirements varied with season but averaged about 13.8 man hours per litter. the price projection for No. l farrows and gilts. Michigan basis. was $13.73 per hundredweight. and the enterprise returned a net revenue of $199.16 per litter to home-produced feed. labor and capital. is Idth the other livestock enterprises. activities were included to represent inveshnent in additional farrowing housing and feeding capacity. WW.«Initial cash holdings were estimated from survey remrns based on estimtes of cash in bank plus saleable crop inventories (see Table 3.6). Activities were included so that additional financing for operations and investments could be obtained against present real estate and chattel assets. as well as from dealers for the purchase of machinery and from private sources. Interest rates were 5.5 percent on real estate mortgage credit. 7 percent on chattel credit. 12 percent on dealer credit. and 1h? percent on credit from private sources. Credit on owned real estate was limited to 50 percent of the net value of real estate assets. Restrictions on chattel 84 credit varied with the class of assets; machinery could be borrowed against up to no percent of the present value. while feeder steers could be financed up to 100 percent of value. as long as sufficient home grown feed was available. The model was designed so that borrow- ing against presently owned assets could be used to finance either operations or new investments in land. buildings or equipment. W. «The model provided that the family labor force could be augmented without limit by hiring of seasonal workers in any or the six time periods. It was assumed that one hour of hired labor replaced .6? of an hour of operator labor. be cost of replacing an hour of operator labor thus came to $2. 02 based on a projected wage of $1.35 per hour for local seasonal workers. Initial restrictions on operator and family labor were based on reported availability. adjusted for age. sex and health. as deter- mined by the survey. Activities representing off-farm employment for the operator in each of the six time periods were also included. Net wage (after deduction of travel costs) was projected to be $1.99 per hour. Family labor could be l'sold" at a net of $1.58 per hour. Restrictions on the quantities of labor sold were based on the average weeks of off- farm labor obtained in the year covered by the field survey. Ww-me model provided for acquisition and disposal of machinery services for tillage. harvesting of small grains and beans. harvesting of corn and corn silage. harvesting of forage. and harvesting and hauling of sugar beets. The estimates of initial capacity for each representative farm were obtained from the average amount of various types of equipment reported in the survey. 85 Annual overhead cost for sugar beet harvesting equipnent was projected to be $11.65 per acre. his estimate was reached by sub- tracting the variable cost of harvesting and a charge for labor from the projected custom rate of $20 per acre.1 filgar beet hauling was assumed to be on the basis of an 8 mile trip to the factory. Hauling capacity overhead cost was estimated at $15.50 per acre. a ti a s.--he linear programming model provided alternatives whereby investment capital could be diverted into purchase of land on a mortgage or under a land contract. as well as for the renting of land. In order to approximate the empirical assmption that the supply of land is not perfectly elastic. it was assumed that 40 acres could be purchased at one price and 1&0 more at a higher price. he prices in Michigan were estimated to be $575 and $690 per acre in the 1966 period. and the prices in Ohio were projected to be $495 and $590. he lower of these prices was reached by project- ing the average of survey responses regarding value of land owned on the basis of the Department of Agriculture's index of land prices. Land could be purchased either on a mortgage basis requiring 50 per- cent down payment and 50 percent mortgage financing. or on a land contract basis where only a 20 percent down payment was required. A question in the field survey questionnaire provided a basis for estimat- ing both the price and quantities of land available for sale and for lhis method of estimation was used for all machinery acquisi- tion activifies in order to meet the difficulties involved in estimat- ing investment costs for durables which are used in more than one crop. such as tractors or combine harvesters. he technique represents a “market valuation." Checking this approach against the more conventional technique of summing depreciation. taxes and insurance and dividing by acres worked per year for single-use durables (beet harvesters. corn pickers) showed that the two methods achieved very close results. 86 rent in the neighborhood of each responding farmer. On this basis it was estimated that each farm operator could purchase 140 acres of land at the projected price of $575. Up to half of this 1&0 acres could be purchased on a land contract. In addition to acquisition through purchase. it was estimated that an additional 80 acres could be acquired through rental arrangements (#0 at each of the two prices). The cash rental rate was estimated on the basis of current share rental arrangements. projected prices and yields. and present distribution by acres of crops on the farm. Land rental cost was estimated at $33.50 and $39.15 for the Michigan districts and $29.40 and $35.50 for the Ohio districts. B. Results of the Static Linear Programming Analysis General he method of solution of the model was in a sense determined by the particular computing facilities that were available. he ccmmter used was the Model 1601+ produced by the Control Data Corporation. At the time the computing equipment was required. the available linear programming routine was somewhat limited in capability. Its variable price feature provided . solution at axw specific price or net revenue combination desired. A more advanced “parametric" technique would indicate corner points or changes in the optimum solution through a specified range of prices. Solutions were obtained for each of the four representative farm situations (see resource organization of the representative farm in Table 3.6. supra) under a number of different price combinations. 87 In addition to the prices shown in Table n.1, solutions were computed for prices approximately 20 percent above and 20 percent below these projections for each of the three crops: sugar beets. beans and wheat. Solutions which were computed for one Michigan district representative farm and for the Ohio district representative farm under several of the more likely price combinations are presented in Tables 14.3. “.1; and “v.5. respectively. he implications of these results for each enter- prise are discussed below in terms of the effect of changing price relationships. changing resource base. and changing enterprise alter- natives. }flchigan Districts he results are presented only for the size farm which was termed "medium" in the Michigan district. he model was solved under two situations. I'Case I" will be applied to the situation where live- stock alternatives were not considered (which corresponds roughly to the present organization in these strata) and "Case II“ to the situation where beef. hog and dairy enterprises were also allowed as alternatives. From the results of the analysis. it will also be possible to show what the effect of a different resource base might be on the optimal solution. he results for Case I (no livestock) are presented in Table ll».3. (Not all. the 27 price combinations which were computed are displayed in these tables. hose combinations chosen for display are the ones judged most significant in their implications or those most likely to occur.) In Case I. where there was no livestock alternative. there was no effect on properties: of cropland in sugar beets under am price of dam 3mm 30m 30m 30m endow azmxwoamzu zmdmnhho w.mm s.~ w.~m m.m~ o.~m ooo.aa erroneom snooeo eospo Has s.m o s.« s.m s.m ooo.H« ersoeeom omoweeoz Hoessso a.sm s.mm s.sm a.sm a.sm ooo.aa eosoeeom omemeeoz sesame doom aHummu om or or or om oeoe assuoenessq ow Hm om om om cued cannonsduvmmn can so: own can can meson sum hoses adsooeom QHMHDcod mmombommm o o o o o 0904 88 Efiésfififim aw om am am am oeoa eeeo m: o: n: m: m: rhea earn: an mm one an an sees seoo msa enH me mad med sees ossom mun oasaem 3m mm hm 3m 3m oped mnoom ammsm ZOHB;zazuosm .Muoamm>ag a as .38 3mm Eguézasmfifi a: zoflfiuaamo Empower game nauseous .3 has 89 beets from $10.60 to $15.10 per ton. his was true even when the price of either dry beans or corn. or both. were at levels 20 percent above that judged most likely to occur. and when the farm did not own the specialized beet equipment. he organization represented by price combination (1}) in Table 4.3. which are the ”most likely" prices. appears to closely approximate .the present organization as determined by the survey data (see Table 3.5). he main differences from present organization of the optimm solution presented in Table 4.3 are the additional acres acquired by renting and through purchase. In this case. the capital resources on the present farms are extensive enough to support an operation of over tides the present size. under the assumption that up to 50 percent of real estate assets may be mortgaged. Off-farm work was utilized to the limit allowed. since there were no livestock enterprises to compete in the winter months. Labor is hired in the summer season to meet the demands of the extra cropland. Case n.-(Livestock activities included.) In this model. the beef feeding. hog and dairy enterprises were included. he results for five price combinations are presented in Table “v.4. 9:92 enLezE-isesw-As in Case I. when sugar boots are priced at the expected level of $12.85 per ton. there is no change in the proportion of crop acreage grown in beets. (The differences in acreages between Cases I and II are due to the different quantities of land acquired under the various price combinations.) However. when sugar beet prices are lowered to $10.60 per ton and bean and corn prices are favorable. the most profitable combination of enterprises does not include sugar beets. This change from the previous case is a consequence TABLE 4.4. PROJECTED OPTIMAL RESOURCE ORGANIZATION AND INVESTMENTS-- 9O MEDIUM FIELD CROP FARM WITH LIVESTOCK. SAGINAW’VALLEY. "THUMB.“ MICHIGAN. 1966 (CASE II) Price Combination No. Price of Sugar Beets Price of Dry Beans Price of Corn ENTERPRISE ORGANIZATION Cropping Program Sugar beets Edible dry beans Corn Wheat Oats Rotation.meadow Livestock Program Grade A Dairy Yearling steer feeding Hogs RESOURCES ACQUIRED One-Use Inputs Corn Hay Seasonal labor U t $ per ton $ per cwt. $ per bu. Acre Acre Acre Acre Acre Acre Head Head Litter Bu. Tons Man hrs 0 Durable Resource Investments Land-purchase Land-rental Milking capacity Beef feeding capacity Hog farrow. & feed. capacity Credit Real estate mart. borrowed Chattel mort. borrowed All other credit borrowed Ofquarm employment —__ Acre Acre Head Head Litter $1.000 $1.000 $1.000 Hours (1) (2) 12.85 12.85 7.20 7.20 1.24 1.04 33 31 143 128 39 33 43 38 29 9 0 l7 2 2 122 208 2 2 O 5.011 32 0 910 1.039 76 40 8O 8O 0 O 43 86 0 0 31.6 26.9 12.0 15.7 22.6 11.6 558 481 (3) 12.85 6.00 1.24 30 30 121 36 19 303 1,088 25 80 134 23.4 15.7 11.6 438 (4) (5) 12.85 10.60 6.00 7.20 1.04 1.24 30 O 30 139 119 69 36 41 0 28 24 0 2 2 312 202 2 2 802 0 2 1+9 1.120 1.013 20 65 80 8O 0 0 138 82 O O 22.1 28.6 15.7 15.7 11‘ O 6 22 O 6 427 42.1 91 of the added value of corn acreage when corn can be fed on the farm. Furthermore. when the model is solved for a resource base which has no inventory of Special beet equipment (that is. harvesting and hauling equipnent must be purchased). with beet. bean and corn prices at $10.60. $6.00 and $1.01}. respectively. the beet enterprise becomes somevdlat marginal (i.e.. the estimated MVP of an additional acre of sugar beets is near zero). The value of corn to the livestock enterprise also changes the competitive relationship between corn and dry beans. Compare Tables 4.3 and 4.4. mth livestock included. corn takes over most of the acreage at these prices at the expense of dry beans. ves enter ses.--The most profitable use of labor. feed and capital was in a yearling steer operation. However. investments would be necessary to embark on such an enterprise. for very little beef feeding equipment is currently available in this area. giggly-Abe hog enterprise appears to be profitable at these prices if there are farrotdng and feeding facilities present. It did not appear to pay to invest in additional capacity beyond that small amount presently available .1 Mw-The dairy enterprise also was not sufficiently profit- able to warrant additional investment. although present capacity is utilized in the model. ksources acggigedw-As compared with Case I. the demand for capital and labor in the beef enterprise reduced the optimal land 1For a detailed analysis of the interrelationships between the corn and livestock enterprises for this rayon. see Lard. pp. 31. . 92 acquisition. Credit use was modified accordingly. with less mortgage credit acquired. but with considerably more chattel credit. used for financing the feeder steers. Off-farm employment was not quite so attractive in the presence of the demand for labor from livestock in the winter. Capital limited the size of the winter feeding operations. so there still was time for several weeks of off-farm work remaining. even with the large beef enter- prise. Ohio Districts Some of the results for the Ohio district representative farm situation are presented in Table 1!. 5. As in the Michigan districts. the sugar beet crop appears to have a strong competitive advantage over typical alternative crops. Soybeans are less profitable in Ohio than dry edible beans are in Michigan. Hence. even under the highest prices for soybeans and corn and a lower price for sugar beets. the beet crop is not forced out of the solution as was the case in the Michigan situations. The profitability should be sufficient to bid in new growers. since the marginal value of an additional acre of sugar beets considerably exceeds the cost of new equipment. the es Remarks on the Appropriateness (or lack thereof) of the Assumptions Predictions about prospective resource organization based on the results of the static analysis must be tempered by judgments as to the degree to which the assumptions of the static model are or will be a«I-'>.'p:l.‘ox:l.mated by existing conditions. A number of these deserve comment. 93 TABLE 4.5. PROJECTED OPTIMAL RESOURCE ORGANIZATION AND INVESTMENTS-- FIELD CROP FARM. NORTHWESTERN OHIO. 1966 (l) 12.85 2.20 1.04 26.1 32-3 4.6 Unit Price Combination No. Price of Sugar Beets $ per ton Price of Soybeans $ per bu. Price of Corn $ per bu. ENTERPRISE ORGANIZATION Croppipg Progpam Sugar beets Acres 45 Soybeans Acres 135 Corn Acres 89 Wheat Acres 51 Oats Acres 5 Alfalfa Acres 32 Livestock Proggam Grade A dairy Head 2 Yearling steer feeding Head 474 Hogs Litter 8 RESOURCES ACQUIRED One-Use Inppts Corn Bushel 9.333 Hay Tons 21 Seasonal labor Hours 2.458 Durable Resoppce Investments Landppurchase Acres 0 Land-rental Acres 80 Milking capacity Head 0 Beef feeding capacity Head 183 Hog farrowing and feeding capacity Litter 0 edit Real estate mortgage borrowed $1.000 Chattel mortgage borrowed $1.000 All other credit borrowed $1.000 Off-farm.emplqyment Hours —— 260 (2) 12.85 2.20 1.24 49 149 100 5? 19 292 2.135 45 80 90 36.3 16.1 0.6 260 (3) 12.85 2.60 1.24 49 1A9 100 57 19 292 2.135 45 80 90 36.3 16.1 4.6 260 (‘0 12.85 2.60 1.04 #5 135 89 51 32 47:. 9.333 21 2.458 80 183 26.1 32-3 4.6 260 (5) 10.60 2.60 1.24 149 100 57 19 292 2.135 #5 8O 90 36.3 16.1 4.6 260 94 Resmge supplies.--The projected optimal organizations imply a large demand for land and for labor. Although some allowance was made for an imperfectly elastic supply of land in the model. it is the opinion of the writer that the supply of land is much less elastic than the assumptions would indicate. Accordingly. the farm size is not likely to be doubled as is implied by the analysis. Supplies of seasonal labor were assumed to be perfectly elastic in the analysis. This seemed to be a reasonably accurate assumption with respect to local summer help under the present organization. However. the increase in demand for labor implied by the added land and livestock operations moves the situation out of the range of the assumptions. Reliable labor is more difficult to locate in other seasons. (This is particularly true for the sugar beet harvest where relatively large amounts of labor competent and reliable enough to trust with the harvesting and hauling equipmentare required.) Ww-me model assumed that credit supplies would be based on the usual practices of institutional lenders. However. the survey data indicated that farmers in effect prefer a much lower ratio of debts to total assets than the limits imposed by lending agencies. Thus. the demand for resources. land in particular but also for labor and capital equipment. would be much less than implied by the model. some doubt that the Field Crop farmers in Michigan districts will continue to have the opportunity to work seasonally off the farm as in the past. Tmporary labor is more and more expensive to employers as fringe benefits become a larger portion of wages. 95 s ack ed e vesto e ses.-The assumptions of the static model (perfectly elastic labor supplies. single valued expectations. and the particular set of relative prices of resources and products which were chosen) contributed to the apparent advantage of large scale beef feeding operations. Although a detailed analysis of this question is beyond the scope of the present stuck. the implications of the static model should be interpreted carefully. First of all. feeding of purchased steers is notably risky. Second. typical sugar beet farmers are not experienced Idth this operation. Third. the assumptions of the model in regard to costs of feeders and sale prices of fat steers. while consistent with the experience of the (relatively favorable) period 1961-62. are somewhat optimistic when compared to the previous 10 years experience in the Corn Belt feeding areas. In the writer's judgment. the degree of shift of resources by sugar beet farmers into beef feeder production implied by the static analysis is thus over- stated. A ms of the Sta del r Su Beet Pr ucti n Res nse The inference to be drawn from this static analysis is that the projected net returns to sugar beets provide this. crop with a substantial net revenue advantage over principal competing crops. It further implies that the suppr relationship will shift to fully utilize capacity avail- able for processing. Returns are sufficient that profit maximizing firms with single-valued anticipations would be expected to commit new ' resources to sugar beet production. This result is rather divergent from the recent experience where beet supplies were insuffident to fully utilize processing capacity. 96 (The short supply however is limited to a few factory districts and is not widespread so the point should not be overemphasized.) In order to test the static model. the problem was recomputed under assumptions about yields and prices approximating conditions in the immediate past growing seasons. The results of this analysis were similar to that reported previously for the projected conditions. i.e.. the expected supplies of'beets would exceed present capacity; however. the advantage fromeeets is not so large or clear-cut.1 (This is equivalent to saying that the technical relationships projected here imply a greater change for sugar beets than for competing crops in 1966 relative to present conditions.) ~To summarize: Static analysis indicates a shift in the supply response relation for sugar beets in the Eastern Region. Application of this model to previous conditions incorrectly forecasts (i.e.. over- estimates) supplies actually forthcoming under those conditions. It appears that the static model must be modified and supplemented before any strong conclusions are drawn. In the next section. we shall consider a number of factors hypothesized to influenoethe production response of sugar beets. C. Other Influences on Sugar Beet Production Response The brief comments on theoretical considerations at the beginning of Chapter III provide a starting point for additional discussion.of influences on supply or production response. Among the difficulties 1Technical coefficients were not changed. There is thus some bias in that present conditions are favorably represented. This is not thought to be serious. The projected changes are mostly in increased yields and reduced cash expenses. both of which are expressed in the net revenues. A: —< 97 explicitly assumed away were nonmonetary goals. response to imperfect knowledge. and distance from delivery points. Some of the above factors are amenable to analysis with the available data; a few directly. others in a more oblique fashion. In the remainder of this section. we will examine some of these problems. The Effect of Dismce {mm Deliven Ppint 9n Neg Memes to Sugg Begts The most important influence on the decision to grow or not to grow sugar beets. given appropriate soil and climatic conditions. is the distance from the farm to the factory. This proposition is well demon- strated in Tables 4.6 and 4.7 which report findings of the field survey described in Chapter III above. The population sampled was composed of farms located on the level lake bed soils where sugar beets are well adapted. Beets are generally delivered to the factory by truck. However. there are several areas some distance from a factory from which the growers truck the beets to a railroad loading point. and they travel the remaining distance in railroad cars. In most. but not all of these cases. the grower pays the actual rail freight charges involved. Deliveries by truck are sometimes complicated by problems of insufficient capacity at the factory or receiving stations. During periods of good weather. the number of loads farmers would deliver must sometimes be restricted by temporary allocations of delivery privileges. Trucks may also at times be forced to wait for some time before being unloaded. these problems are on the way to being mitigated by additional investments in receiving facilities. Waiting times are thus being reduced resulting in a more efficient use of trucks. 98 TABLE 4.6. EFFECT OF DISTANCE TO SUGAR BEET FACTORY ON PROPORTION OF FARMS GIOWING BEETS. 1960* Distance to Haul : Number of : Number : Percent Road Miles : Observations : Grom‘ g Beets : Grgvdng Beets 0 - 5 l9 16 84 6 - 10 5 4 80 ll - 15 29 15 52 16 - 20 15 4 27 21 - 25 12 3 25 26 - 30 0 0 0 More than 30 ‘ 20 0 0 Total 100 I"Source: Random Sample Survey of Economic Class I - V Farms. Saginaw Valley. Thumb Region. Michigan. 1961. (See Lard. Prpfitable kprganizatipn...o . c t.. and Chapt.‘ III. supra. for details of sampling procedure. TABLE 4.7. DISTRIBUTION OF SUGAR BRET FARI~1ERS BY DISTANCE FROM DELIVERY POINT (FACTORY OR RAILROAD LOADING POINT) IN MICHIGAN AND OHIO. 1960* Ead files 399 Delivegz Ppint : Numbep of Farms : Cumulapive Pgrcent O - 5 23 26 6 - 10 17 46 ll - 15 28 78 16 - 20 10 90 21 - 25 8 99 More than 25 1 100 Total 87 *Source: Random Sample Survey of Sugar Beet Growers. Michigan and Ohio districts. 1961. See Chapt. III. supra. for details as to sampling. 99 The effect of distance to the factory on net return to the farmer is from two sources. First. we have the actual additional cost per mile fer labor. fuel. lube repairs. and "user cost.“ The second effect is also important but more difficult to measure. As the time required for a round trip increases. the size of the crew of trucks and drivers required increases also to efficiently utilize the capacity of the harvesting equipment. Individual farms seldom control this much labor or trucking capacity. and it may be difficult and expensive to acquire them. The static analysis of the previous section assumed a single- valued cost for transportation of beets to the factory or delivery point. In the earlier discussion. it was assumed that the beets were hauled a distance of 8-10 miles. Although the hauling costs are masked by the way the data are presented. they approximate $1.50 per ton. On this basis. hauling costs amount to about 12 percent of the total revenues. which is a larger proportion than for fertilizer. or for hand labor. or for harvesting. In this section. effect of additional distances on costs and returns will be demonstrated. Nb first.make the (not unreasonable) assumption that costs involved in loading and unloading a truck are independent of distance to the delivery point. so the additional cost of an extra mile from the factory is just the additional cost of the truck and driver for the extra mile in each direction. Some assumptions as to costs are detailed below: 100 Variable costs of truck per mile: Fuel and lube $0.048 Repairs 0 e050 "User" cost 0,;02 Sub-total $0.20 Driver at $1.80/hour. 30 mphp-additional cost per mile for labor 0.06 Tom $0e26 For each additional mile to the loading point. trucks must travel two miles on a round trip for a variable cost of $0.52. Assume 7 tons per load:l == 30-72 = $.07u3 Cost per ton per mile we assumed earlier that hauling costs were $1.50 per ten for distances up to 10 miles. For 20 miles. the cost would then be $2.24. and for 30 miles. $2.98 per ton. For the 18 ton yield as projected. hauling costs are $27.00. $#O.#l and $53.82 per acre for 10. 20 or 30 miles. respectively. A better than average yield or efficiency of other operations must be obtained to offset the higher hauling costs for beets over the longer distances. Blosser's recent work in Ohio supports this proposition. He notes that the farms reporting higher yields also had a longer average haul.2 1The "average" load will probably exceed this size. with the ‘trend toward tandem rigs. although this size is thought to be more typical. The larger trucks would achieve a per ton cost somewhat lower 'than the above. 2Blosser. R. H.. Qgsts and.Returns from gzoducing Sugg; Beegs in 2&3. Research Bull. 923. Ohio Agr. Exp. Station. Wooster. Ohio. 19 2. 101 The inference to be drawn from this analysis is that net revenue to sugar beets is strongly affected by distance to delivery point. (This explains the relationships exhibited in Tables 4.6 and 15.7.) be competitive advantage of sugar beets is reduced rapidly as the distance to the factory increases. Furthermore. the rate at which the proportion of farmers grow- ing beets declines at distance from the factory beyond 10 miles (see Table 4.6) suggests that factors other than Just the hauling cost per mile (analyzed just above) are of considerable importance. The most obvious of these are the costs of obtaining relatively large supplies of higher quality labor and hauling equipment for the short period required for the best harvest. V a n e S Beet uc One of the most commonly cited influences on sugar beet produc- tion response is that of risks in production and price. It is suggested that large risks are involved in the production of sugar beets which inhibit the response of growers to the favorable price and net income relationships which exist in the Eastern Region. This proposition is tested in the following discussion. The government programs have removed most of the aggregate price fluctuaficns in sugar. There remain some reaonal influences on the level of and variability in net prices to beet sugar (which will be discussed in some detail in Chapter VI). The apparent variability in prices received by growers for sugar beets is due largely to quality differences. The price of beets is based on the recoverable sugar per ton of beets. which in turn depends on the sugar content and purity of 102 the beet. These factors typically exhibit rather wide fluctuations in the Eastern Region. However. there is a marked inverse relationship between tons of beets per acre and recoverable sugar per ton of beets; that is. high yields are associated with low sugar content and 1123 m. Thus. although either of these variables can and do fluctuate widely from year to year. the total sugar per acre. and hence. the gross income per acre. is much more stable (see Column 9. Tables 1 and 2. Appendix II). Two measures of variability are used here. The first measure is the Coefficient of Variability. v=0' 100 T‘ ’ which is just the percent the standard deviation (0") of a series is of its mean (i). It measures the degree of variation from a long term average. The other measure used is a form of “link relative." It has the more desirable properties of measuring year-to-year variability. The assumption that the degree of risk in the decision-maker's mind is I measured by his experience with year-to-year variations seems to be a better approximation to the decision-maker's environment than a measure- ment of the deviation from a long term average. n1. lids-relative measure of variation used here is constructed as follows. First. determine the percent each year's observation is of the preceding year's observation. That is. find the link relatives: {1. 2 f2 3 X0 (100) . X1 (100) . 2 (100) . xt-l. etc. 103 where the subscript i_of each observation refers to the iFh‘time period (;.= 0. 1. 2.....n). Some of the resulting values are less than 100. Take the reciprocal of these so that all numbers are greater than or equal to 100. The measure of variability used here is achieved by taking the unweighted.means of the indices and.subtracting 100 from this value. An.index of 0 thus indicates no year-toqyear variation. The variability'measurements were calculated for sugar beets in both.Hdchigan.and Ohio. and for comparative purposes. for dry beans and corn.in.Michigan. The basic data for corn and beans were for the East Central Counties (where most of Michigan's sugar beets are produced). in order to be on a comparable basis for at least the Michigan beet produc- tion. The variable chosen for the comparisons was gross income per acre. (Similar measures applied to either price or yield per acre series would reveal somewhat higher variability in the case of sugar beets. However. because of the aforementioned.inverse relationship between price and.yie1d. such measures are judged to be misleading.1 .The results of the measurements are presented in Table 4.8. They do not support the hypothesis that income per acre from sugar beets is subject to significantly greater variability than are the principal competing crops. In fact. there is some evidence to indicate the relationship is changing to the advantage of the sugar beet crop. The 15 link-relatives were grouped into three consecutive 5-year periods for 1There is also some doubt as to whether an aggregate series as used here can be an appropriate measure of’year to year variability. One has the intuitive feeling that aggregation would tend to meek a consider- able portion of the year-to-year variation experienced by individual farmers. No data are available to check this hypothesis. 104 each crop. For sugar beets in Michigan during the period 1947-51. the average year-to—year variability (link relative method) was 18.4 percent. In the second 5 years. this measure dropped to 15.4 percent. and the third 5 years to 8.4 percent. The comparisons are more striking for the Ohio series. which changed from 27.0 percent in the first 5-year period to 6.4 percent in the latest 5 years.1 Similar comparisons for corn showed no trend. and an increasing variability was observed for dry beans. TABLE 4.8. MEASURES OF VARIAEELIT'I OF GROSS INCOME PER ACRE FOR SUGAR BEE‘E. m BEANS. OWN. 19446-61" : Edible : Corn: Sugar Beets° Sugar Beets : Beans. : : c : Ohio Link Relative Index 12.1 20.0 14.2 13.9 Coefficient of Variation 13.6 18.0 16.8 12.9 *Data used for corn and dry beans were yield per harvested acre of East Central Counties. Michigan and State average prices. Michigan. 1946-61. as reported in Michigan Agricultural Statistics. Michigan Department of Agriculture. Lansing. various annual issues. Data for sugar beets was taken from U.S.D.A.. Sugar SEflsggs. Vol. II. op. cit. Another measure of risk which is of interest is the proportion of planted acres which are harvested. or conversely. the rate of abandonment. 'mese figures are presented for sugar beets in the Eastern Region in Appendix II. Tables 1 and 2. It is interesting to note that these series also exhibit a trend toward less variability in the most recent periods. lMost of these variations were increases and therefore neither unexpected nor undesirable. 105 The proportion of acres abandoned is a somewhat less useml measure of variabth than might appear at first glance. The acres of beets which are abandoned usually go into dry beans or soybeans. and very few resources are completely lost. In fact. some observers feel that much of the crop that is abandoned in Michigan would produce as good or better an income in beets as it would in beans. even though the stand of boots may appear a little sparse at bean planting time. The abandonment and deficiency payment provisions of the Sugar Act tend to reduce losses sustained by growers prior to harvest. albeit at some cost in "red tape.“ Some consideration was also given to the alternative of measuring net income per acre instead of the gross figures. However. the variations in cost are thought to be considerably outweighed by variations in the yield and price series. Furthermore. there seems to be no convenient method of establishing a series on production costs. ac 3 cs a a The statement is often heard that sugar beet growers are in some sense "a peculiar breed.” different in attitudes and outlook than their neighbors. Should some such differences be demonstrated. it might have some implication for supply response. No part of the questionnaire was devoted to questions on individual attitudes or preferences. so no direct test of these notions can be applied. There are some data which might throw some light on the question. however. The portion of the field survey conducted in conjunction with the Feed Grain Study; provided observations on 42 beet growers and 58 _ 13ee p. 57. suEa. 106 non-beet growers in the Michigan districts. Certain variables which were thought to be of possible influence on supply response were com- pared by standard statistical procedures. It was hypothesized that characteristics such as age. education. not worth. and work off the farm might influence goals or risk preference and hence. production response on sugar beets. Among the variables tested were age of operator. education of the operator. amount of operator and of family labor available at particular seasons. weeks worked at and income from off-farm Jobs. investment in land and in equipment. and net worth. The beet grower group tended to have somewhat more family and operator labor. somewhat more machinery investment. somewhat higher net worth. and less land operated. However. there was no significant difference between the means of the two groups for these or for am other of the variables when tested statistically at even the 20 percent level. a- e nal V a Nat nme t One of the necessary simplifying assumptions of the analysis was that a single technical relation could accurately represent the region. Some of the overcapacity problems of the region are known to be due to differences in natural and institutional enviroment from that Impothesized. For example. the weather data (Table 3.1) shows that the temperature and rainfall conditions in the planting season in Sanilac County. Michigan. are much different from that from other parts of the region. This same area is generally considered to have much poorer drainage than elsewhere in the Michigan districts. (Legal barriers to general drainage programs have recently been lifted. and there is hope that these conmtions will change.) Other factory locations are thought 107 to be less than optimal with respect to favorable soil associations. The data of Table 4.6 demonstrate that a few miles can make a rather large difference in boot supplies. W Perreaultl suggested a list of factors which he hypothesized to be of small individual influence. Motheses about off-farm work. age. net worth and other variables have been examined with inconclusive results. A number of other hypotheses are suggestive but difficult to measure because of their subjective nature. large Capital Investment It is hypothesized that the large investments involved in owner- ship of specialized planting. harvesting and hauling equipment is a deterrent to entry into the sugar beet business. It is quite true that investments are much larger. on the average. than for other crops (see Table 4.1. gm). Furthermore. this cost would be very much larger per acre for a small enterprise than for the average. However. other considerations suggest that this factor should not be weighted too heavily. An active market for custom services exists in the region. It is usually possible to hire these services without incurring the risk of costly excess machinery capacity. Non-monetary Goals If a farmer has goals other than that of musing profits. there are a number of reasons which might cause him to limit or refrain lPerreault. The Acreage fiespgnse of mcggg ragga... 92. g . 108 from the production of sugar beets. Among these fight be included the producer's unwillingness to participate in the government program. Another notion frequenth heard is that nary farmers do not wish to lose the authority over their operations which is implicit in the language of the production contract. Other famers are unable or umdlling to effectively supervise the figrant worker crews required in production of the crop. The production of the crop also may involve a large amount of strexmous labor. perhaps under unpleasant weather conditions during the harvest. (Similar conditions are not uncommon during the hunting season. yet the marginal utility of the latter is high enough for nary to keep them from the beet fields.) Specialized Technical Skills Required Crop and soils specialists who have had a long association with sugar beet production emphasize that special technical skills are neces- sary for successful cultivation of the beet crop. It is implied that inexperienced growers fight be unable to attain the average yields and resource uses that are projected here and therefore would not be likely to comit resources into beet production except at very favorable prices. It is undoubtedly true that sugar beet production presents a number of problems which are different from and more complex than occur in production of competing field crops. Again. the amount of influence this factor exerts is difficult to measure. The previous discussions of trends in technology and the measurements of variability suggest that the importance of these difficulties is declining and that the trend may be expected to continue. 109 D. Sumary and Conclusions from the Analysis of Production Response In Chapters III and IV it has been shown that: (a) (b) Rapid technological advances have greatly increased yields and reduced costs in Eastern Region sugar beet production in the nearly two decades since World War II. Additional increases in yields and reduction in costs are anticipated in the years ahead. Although the sugar beet crop requires very large " supplies of both migrant and family labor and sub- (c) (d) stantial expenses for machinery. equipment and other inputs. its average return per acre on adapted soils is considerably more favorable than that for ary major competing crop under present or projected price relationships . However. there is evidence to indicate that this strong competitive advantage of sugar beets over competing crops is limited to a particular subset of the lake-bed soils in the Eastern Region. Mien the yield relationships for soils other than the 2c classification (Table 3.2) are compared with the costs of production shown in Table 4.1. it is indicated that the advantage of beets nearly vanishes. Distance to the sugar factory is demonstrated to be a major factor influencing the individual farmer's choice of crops. The beet crop is relatively bulky so that hauling accounts for a large proportion of the production 110 costs. Furthermore. the added trucks and drivers required to efficiently support the harvesting crew may often be expensive and difficult to acquire for the short harvest season. Thus. few farmers haul beets in excess of 20 files. (e) There are a. number of other factors which make this crop somewhat of a Spefial case. They are thought to affect production response but in a manner difficult to measure. Therefore. a static model of the profit- maximizing firm has some shortcofings as an analytical tool. (f) The changes in technology of sugar beet production have 6 reduced the importance of some of the special hard-to- measure characteristics. Thus. income variability has been reduced to the point where most of the year-to-year changes are upwards and thus not undesirable. “binning labor is on the farm for only half the time of a few years ago. Harvest and delivery bottlenecks are being eliminated by increased factory receiving facilities. Resistant varieties improve the chances of having a satisfactory gerfination. stand and yield. Implications The implications of the model were that the supply of sugar beets would increase to a point to fully utilize existing and prospective Necessing capacity in the projected period. 111 In view of the considerations just noted and also because of the likelihood of favorable prices in sugar for the next few years. this projection seems realistic. This increase in output can be supplied from present producers by relatively small changes in the present rotations and the eXpected increase in yield per acre. However. should processing capacity be increased substantially. as has been proposed. the answer is somewhat less clear. In a sense. such projections are extrapolations beyond the data. The static analysis indicates that new farmers would be bid into beet production. However. in view of the difficulties in accounting for the subjective factors discussed earlier. subjective judgments as to the behavior of the important variables are required. In view of the data on transportation costs and personal opinions and judgments concerning the preferences and goals of farmers. this writer is not of the opinion that a large proportion (say over 20 percent) of the present non-beet growers on the adapted soil associa- tions would supply beets under the projected price and technical relationships. CHAPTER V SUGAR BEET PROCESSING Some background discussion on the development of the sugar beet processing industry in the United States and in the Eastern Region was presented in Chapter II. In Appendix I there is a chronological history of all sugar beet processing enterprises in the Eastern Region. This chronology shows that most plants in the region. including those presently in operation. were erected around the turn of the century. Of the 34 enterprises launched since 1897. only eight remain. These plants have. in general. increased daily and annual output to a large degree over the years. However. they are still. on the average. of smaller capacity than the average of plants elsewhere. The present chapter will be devoted to an analysis of some economic aspects of the processing of sugar beets. Consideration will be given first to production techniques and input-output ‘ relationships for the industry. A later section will exafine the relative attractiveness of alternative methods of expanding plant “pacify. A. The Production Process and Input-Output Relationships The process of extracting sugar from the beet root involves the following steps :1 lSee McGinnis. R. A.. ed.. W. Reinhold Publishing Corp.. New York. 1951. for a detailed analysis of every Phase of sugar beet processing. 112 113 (a) washing and slicing the beet into thin strips called "cossettes." (b) Removal of the sugar from the cassettes by diffusion (essentially.the cossettes are soaked in hot water. causing nearly all the sugar to move from the cassettes into the water). (c) Partial purification of the resulting diffusion juice by successive treatment with calcium.oxide (lime). carbon dioxide. and sulfur dioxide. and filtration of the resulting precipitates. (The lime and carbon.dioxide are produced at the factory's lime kiln from limestone.) (d) Concentration of the purified juice by boiling in evaporators. (e) crystallizing the sugar in the resulting sirup by boil- ing it in a partial vacuum.until it is supersaturated so that crystals form. (f) Separating the resulting mixture into crystals and sirup by centrifuging. (g) Drying. sizing. packaging and storing the final product. The sirup from the first centrifuging still contains a considerable amount of valuable sugar. It is boiled and crystallized twice more. The sugar resulting from second and third boilings is not of commercial quality. so it.is remelted and re-enters the process. The sirup from the third centrifuging is called "molasses." The solids in molasses are around 60 percent sugar. but the recovery of this sugar by boiling and centrifuging is not economically feasible. Beet.mo1asses is llllr usually sold for livestock feed or for use in the production of yeasts and other microorganisms. It also may be subject to other types of process for extraction of the remaining sugar. The most common of these is called the Steffens process. which is used in a number of factories in the United States. although by none in the Eastern Region. The other by-product. the exhausted cassettes or pulp. is pressed and usually dried for sale as cattle feed. Waste disposal is a major problem of beet factories. McGinnis reports that the waste disposal problem from a 2.000 tan per day (non- Steffen) factory is roughly equivalent to that from a city of 125.000 population} The processing season (or "campaign” is about 100 days duration. beginning around October 1 when the beets have reached a sufficient size and sugar content. The harvest is largely completed by November 1. The length of the processing season in the Eastern Region depends upon the period which the beets may be stored in the factory pile. Toe beets lose sugar through respiration and from such factors as bacterial infections from physical damage or freezing and thawing. 'nxe amount of sugar extracted per ton of beets sliced thus declines as the season progresses. The factory usually maintains some permanent force of about 100 the year around. These include the executive. supervisory and office personnel. a part of the factory work force (which performs the necessary inter-campaign maintenance). and an agricultural staff lMcGinrds. Beet Sggg gechnolgg, 92. 9y... p. 471. 115 who are responsible for the details of acquiring the beet crap. The remainder of the factory crews are hired only for the period of the campaign. New technolggz.-Although the basic process for extracting sugar has not changed for war years. a large number of greatly improved methods and equipment have been developed. The most important of these is the continuous diffuser which eliminates as may as 15 men per shift in replacing the batch-style diffusion batteries. Continuous techniques for mam? other phases. including carbonation and centrifuging for intermediate sugars. have been developed. Automatic control systems for may operations have been introduced. A number of developments in beet storage have contributed materially to a lengthened campaign in recent years. Input-Output Relationships and Measures of Efficiency The list of physical inputs required for operation of a beet factory is too long to cover in detail here. Brief comments shall be offered on those of major importance. §_e_§_t_§_w-The amount and proportion of sugar extracted from the beats depends both upon the quality of the beat and the factory equip- ment and operating techniques. The amount of sugar extracted per ton depends primarily upon the percent of sugar in the beat. The propor- tion of the sugar in cassettes which is finally bagged is further dependent upon the purity of the beet (that is. the proportion of sucrose to total soluble solids in the beet) and the final purity of the molasses (the proportion of sucrose to total solids in the molasses). Cottrell states the point succinctly: 116 For aw particular combination of soluble non-sugars found in factory sirups there is a ratio of sugar to non-sugars which represents the limit beyond which sugar cannot be economically crystallized by ordinary factory processes....If for example. it is found impractical to crystallize sugar beyond a point where the purity of the final molasses is sixty. then it is evident that each 100 pounds of dry substance in molasses contains 60 pounds of sugar and #0 pounds of non-sugars.... every pound of non-sugars has prevented the crystallization of 1.5 parts of sugar.1 Losses of sugar other than that in the molasses generally amount to a quite small percentage of the sugar. According to Cottrell. they may be reduced to less than 0.03 percent of the weight of the beets in non-Steffen operations.2 Eon-Steffen factories average about 80 percent recovery of the sugar in the cassettes. Factories equipped with the Steffens process for treating molasses can achieve an extraction rate of over 90 percent. ’me Steffens process is not universally used. More than half of the most recently established factories in the United States have not included it. The indications are that under the usual price relationships between sugar and molasses. the process does not make 3 The comparison (of extraction rates adequate returns on investment. between regions thus must be made with care. The Eastern Region shows a much lower extraction rate as compared with other areas. at least partly because of the absence of any Steffens operations. Moore has argued that the rate of recovery achieved will depend lCottrell. R. H.. Beet Sugar Egnomics. op. cit" p. 142. id.. p. 146. 3Personal communication. H. M. Bauserman. Stearns-Roger Mfg. Co.. Denver. Colo.. May 24. 1963. 117 upon the particular variant of the share contract in force at a given factory. The processors whose share allows him but 50 percent of any increment of sugar extracted would not find it to his advantage to extract as much sugar as would the processor who received the entire marginal unit.1 The Eastern Region contract is of the former type. This may account for a part of the differences between regions. although the proposition would be extremely hard to test because of the variation in the primary factor influencing recovery rates. the amount of impurities in the beets. _L_a_}_:_>_9_r_-,.-Generally speaking. the labor required per unit (whether measured inputs of beets or‘ output of refined sugar) depends on the particular types of equipment installed in a factory and the scale of the operation. as well as on the quality of the beets. Kinsley reports a mean of .86 man hours per ton and a range of .62 to 1.29 man hours per ton of beets sliced in a study of six United States beet factories in 1.952.2 flaw-Several million gallons of fresh water per day are required for fluming. washing. diffusion and for the boilers. The amount of fresh water used depends upon the degree of recirculation. particularly in the fluming. Mw-Large quantities of steam are required at a number of different points in the extraction process. Accordingly. beet sugar lMoore. J. R.. "Economic Implications of Share Contracts for Contracts for Sugar Beets.” ognal of gm Econogcs. Vol. XLIV. No. 2. May. 1962. zKinsley. a. T.. Case St\_1_dy Data on Prguctivity and Factogy Pegfgrmance: Beet Sugar gefinigg. BIS Report No. . U.S. Dept. of Labor. Washington. D.C.. February. 1953. 118 factories are equipped with a large capacity boiler system for the production of steam to be used in the evaporators. vacuum pans. and various juice heaters. Steam is also usually used to generate the plant's electric power. A system designed for the most efficient use of steam can make rather large economies in fuel consumption. The average reported by Kinsley was about 220 pounds of coal to boilers (basis 10.000 BTU per pound of coal) per ton of beets. but the most efficient plant achieved a rate of less than 160 pounds.1 Pulp dryer coal requires an additional 75 Pounds of high grade coal per ton of beets (14.000 BTU per pound). Cake is the usual fuel in the lime kilns. although some use of natural gas is reported. Cake is required at a rate of 10 to 20 pounds per ton of beets. mesgnew-A good grade of lime rock is required for conversion to calcium oxide. A typical quantity would be at a rate of 100 pounds per ton of beets processed. mw-Lesser quantities of a number of other materials are required in the extraction process. including sulmr. diatomaceaus earth (for use as a filter aid). soda ash. filter cloth. activated carbon. bags and the like. The efficient and profitable operation of a given beet factory depends. among other things. on an adequate volume of high quality beets. Both quality and volume have been and are problems of Eastern Region processors. The content of sugar and the extraction rates have been somewhat lower on the average than in other regions.2 _ 111nm. Table 8. ZSugar Statistics. Vol. II. gm" Tables 20, 21 and 22. 119 More of a problem has been volume of beets supplied. It was shown in Chapters III and IV that a most important determinant of the relative profitability of the beet crop to the farmer was the quality and fertility of the soil. Furthermore. the importance of transporta- tion costs for beets indicates that a processing plant must be located in immediate proximity to large bodies of favorable soils in order to obtain adequate supplies without incurring special costs or subsidies. he history of declining factory numbers in the Eastern Region appears to be in large part attributable to the location of many of the plant sites in areas where the soil characteristics do not provide a margin of advantage to the beet crop. A chronically low volume of production is financially disastrous to a firm with the high overhead costs for capital equipment and permanent staff involved in beet production. B. Returns to Alternative Methods of Adding Plant Capacity The recent interest in the possibilities of expanding beet sugar production in the Eastern Region suggests that some consideration be aven to alternative methods for achieving such ends. The problem is of rather a complex nature. and the subsequent analysis may reflect a larger probability of error than the author considers desirable. There exists no public information on the detailed costs of operating a beet factory. The operating firms naturally do not publish amr such information. (The Sugar Division of the Department of Agri- culture has this type of data for purposes of administering the Sugar Act but only on a confidential basis. and "outsiders" such as the author are not permitted access.) 120 The procedure followed here was to construct a fairly detailed budget of the operating requirements of three hypothetical sugar plants. To arrive at estimates of operating costs. assumptions were made as to the quantities and unit costs of various categories of inputs. includ- ing beets. labor and materials. and capital equipment. These assumptions are presented in Tables 5.1. 5.2 and 5.3. The resulting income and expenses will then be compared as to their rate of return on invested capital. Certain specific and limiting assumptions are required for this analysis. The capital investment in a sugar plant must be recovered over the plant's operating life of 40 or more years. The cost of the various other resources. labor. coal. lime rock and various and sundry operating supplies may be expected to increase over time. The use of present prices. as was done in this analysis. is equivalent to the assumption that sugar prices and the efficiency of resource utilization will change at rates sufficient to precisely offset expected increases in costs for other purchased resources. Q§§2_I,-In this instance. we assume a hypothetical plant with a capacity'of 1.600 tons daily. It is proposed to remodel the existing facilities and equipment to reach a capacity of 2.400 tons. Assumptions as to the investment required are listed in Table 5.3. It is assumed that a continuous diffuser will be installed and equipment purchased to replace and add to existing yard. beet end and sugar end facilities. A bulk storage silo for 100.000 hundredweight is included. Labor and material input assumptions are shown in Tables 5.1 and 5.2. respectively. This plant would draw'on 15.000 acres of beets at present.yields. 121 TABLE 5.1. PROIXJCTION AND RELATED LABOR REQUIREMENTS FOR THREE HYPOTHE'HCAL SUGAR BEET FACTORIES : Factory : Factory : Factory : No. 1 : No. 2. : No. 3 Operation : 2400 tons/day : 3000 tons/day : 4500 tons/day : (partly modernized : (modern : (modern = W a segment) : e e t Men.§§guired per 8 £92; Shift Beet Ehd Handling (fumes. trash catchers. beet washers) 7 5 Slicing (picking table. knife filters. weighers) Diffusion" Carbonators Filters. Laundrymen Evaporators Utility Fwwm V HNHVNH? wacwwm HNHmHHm Sugar End Boilers. Crystallizers. Helpers Granulators Centrifuges. Melters Packaging. Warehouse Utility Fbreman |...n O\ \1 (DV UV) l—‘l-‘waNU N O‘O you l-‘NO‘P'N-P' lime Kiln Boiler House Laboratory (chemists. samplers) Pulp Dryers Maintenance (machinists. mechanics. electricians) General (sweepers. janitors. supply handlers. etc.) H O\ \O O\O\ #«F’ HHNPNN |'-’ G) N 2% H O H Average per Shift Average Production and Related Labor per Ton of Beets Sliced .82 S9 ‘ljllllll'lll . ‘1 122 N300. Naoo. N300. 00.0m cos no. no. no. n~.s cos amo. amo. amo. on.ma cos mo. mo. Ha. om.m cos an. mm. mm. as.m asoa ea: eoo m mecca a sea to moan: oxoo xoom 08.3 .pa\sem coo.sav gowns mesa o» aaoo A.na\pam ooo.oav maoflaom as dean some..." confined Be cofioseohm thaw, ” anew. “ sec ago» co: m “ Anaemia \mc3 00m! a . \acop 000.0 « Aeoaaeosoa « had a Autopoem 333 » Annapoeh 323 « heaped.“ wcflmdnav ” mowed « page H m .02 huopoem « N .02 heapoem “ H .02 heapoem a . 83H 3504..“ 30% swam ggsoa é mzounomzamg amoo 924 HDiZH Aden—”mam .N.m an. 123 .dflameo msfiesado use used mo 03”.; mead H.333 aaneuaaasau no ed....eb Ho fiestasoh .hdso scan—pegs." 302W 000.mH 0nu.ad 003.: \mpsosueonsH omeua>< mafia” mains 034 358 0Nm 00M “N gonna use eadosamsdpsoo mm mm 0H smdeon use msduoosawsm 00m 00m ma eefiudflaaem soavoenumsoo huesodsea Reg: 966 8m A62: as .85 ads .ooafio .ESSBJ .wsdwexoed semen .hopeaesom .saaaon .sadx osda .usa semen .uso poop .omeos emery Aeosafiflmfi 333050 handguns 000.N 00H.N oom “asap sass use oesosowez semen .omsosases use nehwu sass .sopesosom use seaaoo .eesos sHHx esda 9soon losope use some asdsoes .eese msawexaea .2335 boosts: e5 Sacco is semen use noon wsausaosa .msauaasn.saesv emsauaaem 000.m 000.: 0mm A.opa .eassam .msoomeH annex .haadse have: .psosmdswo wsa>daooa use 33.3 .msflroefiwea .useav asasmaswo use museh buosoeh aseaaon 000 lHalqo noises ” 3 8 u so 08 w o u t 3oz » saz . on heu\sop 000 no " aevH m .02 auopaem « N .oz hsopoeh “ soapauue an wsdaouosam « u » Kmm .oz hhopoem I!“ agedh doflgog Ea mom mazEHEZH Asa—Ha .n.m 3mg 124 Case I; and Case law-These are hypothetical new plants. Assuming that a site could be acquired suitably located with respect to supply of beets and water. on a rail spur and with sufficient acreage for waste disposal and beet storage areas. costs might be as in Tables 5.4 and 5. 5. Each plant is assumed to have the following types of equipment: continuous diffuser. continuous first and second carbonation system. and automatic centrifugals. None of the special processes (Steffens. ion exchange. or continuous adsorption) are included in the cost of equipment. (Each of these improves quantity or quality of sugar extracted at an additional cost in capital and materials.) Bulk storage bins are included to the extent of 200.000 and 300.000 hundredweight. respectively. The labor requirements assumed do not reflect a particularly high level of automatic controls.1 These plants would draw on 19.000 and 28.000 acres of beets. respectively. for 100 days of operation (current yields). The additional investment in Case III as compared to Case II was estimated by a method reported by Chilton.2 The assumptions with respect to performance rates imply a some- what greater efficiency in use of labor and fuel in Cases II and III than in the remodeled plant. It is assumed that extraction rates of sugar 1Data on costs and input-output relationships which provided the basis for estimation for new plants were generously provided by H. M. Bauserman. Stearns-Roger Mfg. Co.. Denver. Colorado. Personal Comunica- tions. April 1. 1963. and May 24. 1963. ZChilton. c. E.. "'Six-Tenths Factor' Applies to Complete _ Plant Costs." in Chilton. C. E.. ed.. Cost Estimation in the Process Industries. New York. McGraw-Hill Book Co.. Inc.. 1 0. p. 282. 125 TABLE 5.4. INCOME AND EXPENSES PER TON OF BEETS SHW-HPOMECH FACTORIES : Factory No. 1 : : :(Ehcisting factory : Factory No. 2 : Factory No. 3 z : remodeled) : (New facto ) (New factory) : 2.400 Ensldaz 3 2.000 @352; 1 5.529 mmlm Income - Net Proceeds i Er Tgn 5 a; Ton § a: Ton Sugar 240 lbs. per ton @ $8.00 per curt. 19.20 19.20 19.20 Dried Pulp 103 lbs. per ton @ $33.00 per ton 1.70 1.70 1.70 Molasses 96 lbs. per ton @ $22.50 Per ton 1.08 l008 ;:08 ' 21.98 21.98 21.98 Expenses (not including marketing expenses) Payments to Growers (50%) 10.99 10.99 10.99 15% of excess of $7.50/th. .18 .18 .18 SUb-tOtal 11017 11.17 1101? Production and Related “bar 2003 1054 1031“ Fuel to Boilers 1.05 0.76 0.76 Pulp Dryer Coal 0.54 0.54 0.54 Coke 0.13 0.13 0.13 Limestone 0.21 0.21 0.21 General Property Taxes 0.17 0.50 0.44 Depreciation 0.92 1.93 1.65 All Other Expenses 3.44 3.36 3.20 Total Expenses (excluding Federal income tax) 19.66 20.14 19.44 Income Less Ehcpenses 2.32 1.84 2.54 126 Axe» osoosd use weapons“ anomonv mm.m m&.¢. mu.ma asosveo>sH omewo><.so shaver no open Axes aeoasa 086:; 8063 Somme esteem .5235 2830 282s ooz 25 as 80 om 0 we eefiesoheon Segre; 80.02...” Seek. osoosH asses "nuances sonflo we “once"...sosmma 408 ea 38 moose so peso 3 034 ooo ewe someones. 850 3 8°de 0863 08:3 ease heroes Hetero 80.8 08.16 084m 88.823 086m 806m 086m 880 80.3“ 8043 80.34 eons use use deco 805a ooodmm Scene esofiom nos deoo 828m. 80.32 08$? “reassess . e33 eooeaoe one sofloseoea oooémoé 80435» 08.89% soaksfla a 228.8 3 Barge eoesodxm Sergei 08.:me Sesame» erase ooz 80.8: ooormfl I ooo m consumes a memmeaos .muaooosm poz ooofiea 8°.on 8°63 e3\oo.m$ a mass peas .muoooosa paz 80.39% 8208.3 0868i 68393 e semen mo modem .muaooosa aoz OSOOGH league 8%: a 33308.? a 3% or scale " Ahuooaem sozv a Ahuoaaem.3azv . Asoauesfisneuos eaoev a m .02 hwopoem a N .oz auouoem » Aesopoem msaumaumv a a a H .oz hwoaaeh « chumzom .mpodponm muden .mum:oupoomqoo .noxem on muo>daoo moosaocH\m .aN magma .mema mdpmpm as am .mmm :apoaaem Hecavmapwpm .oaspasoanm4 Ho .pdon .m.D "mafipnom codpwnwaanmpm haddoeaoo "moondom £982 :5 .oz .3 as .H 40> .38 efiaaom e5 8 lfiO Icoz \m www.mma m.¢e mom.mm H.mm mam.mm meme mon.mma m.ee meo.Hw m.nm mm:.:m Home mms.mea e.ee moa.mm w.mn mmm.om some mam.eea m.me onm.mm N.Nm mem.mm mama mom.eea ~.on 3:3.Nm m.me mom.am mmma moo.mma m.ms mea.mm H.Hm mmm.am mmma HNm.HeH m.om wee.am s.me nme.mm mama mmm.mna m.Hm see.mm ~.ws emm.mm mama eam.mea o.mm mmw.mm e.e¢ Hmo.me :mma mmH.~mH m.mm ome.am m.w¢ mme.om mama mma.eea m.mm mme.aw ~.ss mmm.:e mama mmm.mmH m.mn www.mm ~.:s mmm.ae Hmma emo.ona m.mm mmm.wm m.me msm.mm. omma mmm.ema «.mm Hom.mm m.as m-.mm mama u we a no » omen: . amp 9 u ‘Imwo “ H308 » #Gooyom u HdmémfigH « abouhom « Hd @934an « .HdoH HI! was Hmzvonccdm 000 H In! \mmmumema .mmwam mo mama mm macaw mo mmHmm>Humn .m.e mamas 141 canning industry. Certain bacteria. termed "thermophilic" which can survive the high temperatures in the preserving process must be eliminated from the sugar used. These changes create certain difficulties for the producer of sugars. To obtain a liquid beet sugar. it must be remelted from dry sugar which adds somewhat to costs for this product. The large invest- ment in bulk storage facilities for both dry and liquid sugars return little to the processor in the form of increased efficiencies in handling. They are necessary expenses in order to retain the firm's cmmpetitive position in his natural markets. The sugars produced to high specifica- tion are more costly. for they may require special agents. or they may reduce the rate of factory operation. The tendency to store sugar in bulk silos means that all sugars in the silo must meet the standards of practically all users. Thus. the sugar sold for household and other consumption meets specifications well beyond what is actually required.1 Com. ve ends n the ndus a1 Users Market In view of the increasing importance of the industrial demand for sweeteners. a field survey of various types of users was conducted as a portion of this study. (Table 6.6 shows the types of buyers of sugar and the quantities taken by each.) Although the relatively larger portion of Eastern beet sugars marketed in consumer packs makes this analysis somewhat less important than anticipated for the present problem. some general impressions are of interest and will be recorded. 1Cottrell. R. H.. Speech delivered to meeting of California Beet Sugar Technologists. February 21. 1959. 142 ..mh0»dbflhpmdo muqsaad an moaho>aaoo Ho poached N.mm haopmsaxowddu upcomowdom .dw edema .mme .goudz .HMH .02 .m» 0 mm e um «condoms mmm.am o msm.ma wee.ma “somaxuumgsv xasm ea moauosaaon oHH.mm new msm.m: mmm.m “.mna on case umoHV «seam oudm Magmaoo ca moauourflnon www.mma mme.m Num.e~H ama.ms mmHmmsaqma A4309 mom.mm wee.m mmm.oe mmo.ma Hapoa.nsm eaa.~ m Hmn.a 0mm moaocoma,pcaaquo>oo msavsaocH moauo>aaon nonpo AH< mme.m~ awn mam.ma mnm.n monopm sauna .muoooao assume mmm.om smo.m Hem.mm edemaa “tonnes .m¢apcoogg.m~¢moaoez Sm; m mam; S 803333 .mpfigfimom .mafiom Hddfimfivcmlnoz mam.mm mma.m nmm.oe mma.mm Haooannam Hmm.a sea sms.a mm apogeOhm eooa.:oz m:m.m 0mm mma.s 0mm some coca tango use aaaapaaz omm.ma NHH.H mo~.m oam.m mosuommum .moaaaoe .maae .mooom sonoyh .ooappom .oocsoo mms.em mm: moe.o~ mmm.m momuuo>om mmm.m one mmm.m mmm.m nauseoum awash ecu smote ooH www.ma mam m-.~H mmm.e mooseoam eopaaom muocoaoooocoo HH¢.N~ mam mom.sa mma.m nauseoum .. eoaaaa ecu Haouoo .muoxam as use: 0: 0 o 000 IIIIIAMMdHI; 1.0.n eons SH “ case somwll ” amme .m Rafi—Ham :an coo...” \flNmmH egmHMImeH mmmoaoo .mzonnoflm 92¢ madam Hm 35m .3 ZOHHBEmHQ nzd zofloonommdamg .56 g .‘lyl ...i 151+ TABLE 6.1}. Continued 3‘] Sources: Production an! Receipts. Mainland Cane Production from Sugar Remrts 115. Table 5; Sggar Repozts 118. Table 5. and Sggar Repggts 122. Table . Beet area production-U.S. Beet Sugar Association. Offshore raws (converted to refined basis) from Sgga: fipggts 120. Table 30. and Sugg Remzts 1.3:}. Table 26. Offshore Direct Consumption Sugars - Sggg Repgzts 120. Table 31. and Suga; Remrts l3}. Table 27. Distribution—83g” Remrts 118. Table 16. and Sugg; Repggts 122. Table 16. 13! Production and receipts include raw sugar shipped to inland points for refining. The basis price for sugar in the Eastern beet and Chicago West territories has often times been somewhat lower than that quoted at sea- board refinery points in recent years. This is not surprising. in view of the competition of surplus sugars from all the surrounding regions. ‘Jhus. the sugar market of Chicago and vicinity has been called the "great dumping ground of homeless refined sugars."1 as sugar is shipped in by producers in other areas. in order to avoid ruining their home markets.2 The declines in Midwestern price have been generally attributed lCottrell. get Sgga; Eggnggcs. op, gt" p. 336. 2n... behavior of this market appears to be explained by the notion of price discrimination in imperfect markets. The relatively high transportation costs to an extent insulate each producing area from others. and in the large competitive market in the North Central states each producer would face a demand of greater elasticity. It pays the firm to equate marginal cost with marginal revenue in each market. and the price would be lower in the more competitive market with the greater elasticity of demand. See Boulding. K. E.. Econgrgc My 3rd ed.. Harper Bros.. New York. 1955. p. 611. 155 to the competition of increasing supplies of beet sugar. Growth of out- put in the Western and Central states' beet areas has outpaced popula- tion growth. and these sugars have had to penetrate the Midwest in search of markets. Price concessions have been necessary in order to effect this penetration. in addition to the freight absorption required to market Western and Central beet sugar in the Midwest. Table 6.8 demon- strates the relationship between total beet sugar production and market- ings of beet sugar in the East North Central states. Another element which should not be overlooked is that the North Central Region is the point of origin of almost all corn sweeteners. which intensifies the competition for the sweetener market. Effects on the Eastern Region The effects of these competitive conditions on the basis price and net proceeds to beat sugar have been of considerable concern to the Eastern beet producer. A number of factors are thought to contribute to the particular effects on the region. First. the Eastern producers are price takers. even in their home markets. Hence. the competitive behavior of major cane and beet suppliers is the major influence on the market. Also. the structure of transportation rates is such that a more favorable freight absorption from other beet areas can be obtained for sugar sold in portions of Lower Michigan than in. for example. Illinois.l Thus. beet sugar is shipped into Southern Michigan in competition with leeskin. s. a. (Lamborn and Co.. Sugar Brokers. Saginaw. Mich.). Markng Michigan Beet Sugar. Speech at Sugar Best Day. Michi- gan State University. January 28. 1958 (processed). 156 TABLE 6.8. BEET SUGAR PRODUCTION. U.S. AND EEET SUGAR DISTRIBUTION. EAST NORTH CENTRAL STATES. 1914-9-62 : Beet Sugar : : B. Sugar Deliveries Crop Year : Production : Calendar : East North gjntral (beginning Oct. 1) : U.S. ° Year : States 41.000 mast—la. : 0 s e ed 1948 1 . 227 1949 (+53 1949 1.503 1950 573 1950 l . 883 1951 568 1951 1.1.2.0 1952 1.37 1952 1.419 1953 554 1953 1.750 1951+ 595 1954 1.868 1955 ' 579 1955 1.617 1956 62.1 1956 1.843 195? 762 1957 2.068 1958 829 1958 2. 068 1959 823 1959 2. 151 1960 779 1960 2. 313 1961 l . 010 1961 2.263 1962 902 2‘! Source: Adapted from U.S.D.A.. Sugar Division. Sugg Statisggs and Related Data. Volume E. Washington. D.C.. 1959. Table 2. and Sugar figmgts 125. September. 1962. Table 29. yEast North Central States are msconsin. Illinois. Indiana. Michigan. 0hio--Source: U.S.D.A.. Sugar Division. Sggar Statistics and Related Data Volume I. 1961. Table 12. and Sugar Reports 1;} . February. 1963. Table 18. 15? local sellers. There is also the influence of truckers who avoid empty runs back from Chicago by purchasing sugar at cut rates and hauling it back to Michigan for a small margin. Furthermore. the long existence of a beet industry in the Eastern Region assures the acceptability of the beet product in this area. a consideration which does not always hold true in areas further East which have had little or no experience with beet sugar. The actual effects of these forces on net proceeds are some- what difficult to demonstrate. The actual price may be considerably below that listed. due to unannounced discounts and allowances. A Sugar Division official. in response to a query from the author concern- ing the reliability of the various price series on sugar. replied as follows: ....The extent and variety of unannounced discounts and allowances have increased markedly and the development of a comparably reliable adjusted price series for more recent years seems out of the question. For many years. the Michigan producers have quoted a lower price in the Southwestern Michigan ”coffin corner" market. For example. a trade publication in late 1962 stated. "Michigan beet processors list $9.15 in the lower peninsula of Michigan. and $8.80 in the Southwest corner of the state."2 The United States Department of Agriculture price series for lPersonal conmmnication. July 25. 1962. Herbert G. Folken. Program Analysis Branch. Sugar Division. U.S. Dept. of Agriculture. 2Lamborn Sugar-Market Report. Vol. XL. No. I+5; (weekly) Lamborn and Co.. New York. Nov. 5. 1962. 158 Eastern beet sugar does not include the price required to meet competi- tion in the Southwestern part of Michigan. Hence. this quotation reflects the extent of these influences only when the competitive area extends throughout Michigan's lower peninsula. This occurred. for example. in 1961 and the average basis price for Eastern beet sugar was below the Chicago-West figure for that year. (See Table 6.9.)1 Effect 9f competitive factgrs on net prgceeds ’29 Eastegg beet producerswg-The above difficulties with the official price series led to a search for other relationships. The variable of most interest to the beat industry is "net proceeds."2 The Department of Agriculture does not compute a separate series on net proceeds for individual regions. However. an approximation for the Eastern.Region was developed by use of other available data. The Department does publish series by regions on (a) payments to growers per ton of beets ard (b) on recovery of refined sugar per ton of beets. These data and assumptions as to the typical Eastern region arrangements for sharing net proceeds pro- vide a basis for an approximation.3 1’In that year. the initial U.S.D.A. consumption estimate (measured on a per capita basis) was somewhat larger than had been typical. Prices in all regions suffered. but the effect was greatest in the marketing area for Eastern beet sugar. See Table 6.9. 2The concept of "net proceeds" was introduced in Chapter III. It refers to the return per cwt.of sugar after specified marketing and shipping charges have been deducted. In effect. this is the net price shared by grower and processor. 3The resulting series is no more than an approximation. file basis for payment includes the share of by-products. The amount of pulp and molasses derived per ton of beets varies somewhat from year to year. as do their prices. Also. in some years special bonuses may be included in the payment to growers. which would be unaccounted for due to lack of data. .ueosmsoaae use upssoemdb awe pounce use shunned pmwaeam new .eOHnd veaebHHeo ebaweo ha .moeHud veaepfiaoo.mmm .mwen .QH ooH .meednd «Hmem\m 159 .0 up mm e am H. 1143;... 3 .fimmw .H .Ho> .Idneo efi.lflm.mfl.slm .593»? to ...Ed .ms .838} ao.m mm.m nH.m no.m mH.m ow.m me.w NwaH mm.m mm.m ou.m m~.m 0H.n oe.m on.o HomH mu.m am.m mm.w mm.m nH.m ms.m on.w ommH Ha.m am.w mm.m mm.m mo.n mm.m su.o mmmH Hm.m ww.w mm.m wo.m oo.n mm.m mm.w mama mw.m Nh.m Nm.m mm.m Hm.~ mH.m :~.o mmmH mm.m wm.m mm.m om.m mw.m mm.m mo.w wmma mn.m am.m me.m om.m so.~ mm.m ma.m mmmH om.m mm.m on.w mm.w mm.m mm.m mo.w nmma mm.w Nn.m om.w om.w m:.m mm.m mm.w mmma Nr.m Hr.w Hm.m mm.m om.~ «h.w h~.e NmaH wH.w NH.m wm.m mm.m mm.m mm.m no.0 Hmma ~m.a om.a oo.m oo.m ao.~ oo.m mm.m ommH Hw.m mm.m Ho.m Ho.m wH.N mm.m Hm.m mama - - I I -.~ ha.m sm.m mamH I I I I wo.~ mm.m HN.w mama “mmmMWAmmfihmnmmw snowmen u a . « onmeH0h3 » edsmeaomx « oasmoaohz aoHemoHoaz “ campus ”oflemoaogz uxaow.soz « use» nemsm poem“ usmsm poem” aemsm oneoaaemsm endouaeedvonoomauwsmsm edeoaaemsm.smma oosdmom “ vosflom a wear—Gem a .38—Hum “ .muosfiwom a oosflom a a mh-armH .mu4mm>¢.A49224 .mdmm<.wm .xga meHz .mmonm andmmgomz mdwsm 9mmm 924 made amaomumm .m.o mHm¢H 3m. ‘1" Pa 160 An attempt was made to measure the various influences on this approximation to net proceeds by statistical techniques. It was hypothesized that net returns (which is denoted N) were influenced by (a) the general price level for sugar (denoted Ps)' and (b) the supply of best sugar (denoted Ob). and (c) a random component (denoted u). N: f (P50 013' 11) A number of variables were tested before arriving at a final combina- tion. Due to the provisions of the Sugar Act. the general price level of sugar was assumed to be predetermined. Since the wholesale cane sugar price was the variable defined by the legislation until mid-1962. it was used as an independent variable to represent the general price level of sugar in the equation. Several variables were tested as measurements of beet sugar supplies. including total beet sugar production and per capita and total beet sugar deliveries to the East North Central Region. The variable which contributed most to the explanation of the variation in the dependent variables was total deliveries to the East North Central Region. Each of these variables was fit by standard least squares techniques to equations of linear and logarithmic form. The logarithmic form explained the largest proportion of variance in the dependent variable. The resulting equation. based on time series data for crop years 1949-1961 was: log N = .1944 + .9258 log Ps - .1493 log Qb {-26) (.33) (~07) 112: .tI6 161 (Numbers in parentheses are standard errors of the regression coefe ficients.) The signs of the coefficients were as hypothesized. The regression coefficients were tested to determine if they were significantly different from zero. The 1; statistic was calculated to be .74 for the intercept. 2.84 for the coefficient of sugar price. and 2.04 for the coefficient of beet sugar deliveries. Thus. the coefficient of sugar price is the only coefficient significant at the 5 percent level.1 Taking derivatives of the equations for the region (at the mean) it was found that a 100.000 ton increase in.deliveries of beet sugar to the East North Central Region was associated with a $0.18 decline in net proceeds per cwt. in the Eastern Region and a $1.00 change in the wholesale price of refined sugar in New York was associated with a $0.71 change in net proceeds. The necessity for utilizing an approximation probably accounts for some of the relatively low explanatory values encountered (R2 = .46). The effect of these same independent variables on net proceeds to all beet sugar delivered in the United States was also measured as a matter of curiosity. The resulting regression coefficients were of similar magnitude to those estimated for the region but were all significant at the one percent level. and the coefficient of determina- tion was relatively large (R2 = .85). 1The value of 3 must exceed 1.81. 2.23 and 3.17 for signifi- cance at the 10 percent. 5 percent. and one percent levels. respectively. (Ten degrees of freedom.) 162 The statistical analysis indicates that the increasing supplies of Western beet sugar have an important influence on prices and net returns to Eastern beet sugar producers. The announcement of plans to construct additional facilities in Central and Western beet growing areas indicates that this problem is likely to become more serious in the future. unless beet sugar producers in those areas are able to enlarge their share of markets close to their producing areas. Conclusions In summary. then. the net proceeds from the sale of Eastern Region beet sugar are influenced by (a) the general level of sugar prices in the United States. (b) the average distance from the factory to point of delivery. (c) the quantities of sugar (particularly beet) which are marketed in the region. and (d) the proportion of sugar distributed in consumer markets. The effects of these factors vary over time. largely with the supplies and competitive behavior of the larger elements in the market. ca us an n.--‘ll1e inferences to be drawn from the previous discussion is that expansion of output in Eastern areas at a rate faster than the normal growth of the market could be expected to decrease "net returns” per bag to some extent. The larger outputs would have to be sold in more distant markets at additional transporta- tion costs. More intense competition would likely be encountered. particularly in the industrial sectors of these markets. Price conces- sions might be required to penetrate consumer markets in areas not presently familiar with the brands. 163 However. even a large increase in production in the Eastern Region (relative to present levels) would not change the region's role as price-takers in the large Midwestern sweetener market. The major influences on prices (aside from the government) will continue to be the competitive actions taken by the large suppliers to the market. CHAPTER VII SUMMARI AND CONCLUSIQNS Sum—m Beet sugar production in the Eastern Region (Michigan. Ohio. Maconsin. Illinois and Indiana) in the past. three decades has been characterized by a decline in the level of production. both absolutely and relative to other areas. Michigan and Ohio contain the only remaining production locations in the Region. Recent developments. in particular rapid technological advances in sugar beets and changes in the federal statutes governing the sugar industry. have raised questions concerning the feasibility of expanding beet sugar production in the Region. The purpose of this study has been to examine the trends and changes in the economic. techniml and institutional factors influencing the industry and which determine the advisability of expanding output. The analysis has focused on the present producing localities in the Eastern Region. although there is some relevance to the other states. W.ume domestic sugar irmstry operates under a complex system of governmental controls . The Sugar Act authorizes the Secretary of Agriculture to determine the supply of sugar which will result in prices which are fair to consumers and will serve to maintain the domestic industry. These goals are implemented by a quota system whereby each producing area. domestic or foreign. is assigned a quota 16h 165 which it may sell in the United States' market. For mam years the quota arrangement operated effectively to stabilize prices at reason- able levels. This form of program can successfully stabilize prices only when world supplies are large relative to consumption. as has been the case during most ofpthe past four decades. When the world stocks of sugar became relatively small in the early months of 1963. the United States' price of sugar followed the rapid advance in the international market. since nearly half of United States' needs are purchased from foreign sources. be short run inelasticity of sugar supply and long lead time required for adding processing capacity indicate that world supplies will be relatively short for at least two to three years. flaw-Juan beet production in the Eastern Region. as elsewhere. has undergone a dramatic transforma- tion in the period since World War II . Formerly the heavy seasonal demands of the crop for labor were met by importation of migrant field workers. However. the introduction and adoption of mechanical harvesters some years ago eliminated the need for the migrant labor in the beet harvest period. The development of monogerm seed varieties and mechanical stand reduction techniques have reduced by half the demand for field workers in the spring thinning period over the past six seasons. Chemical and mechanical means are reducing field labor for weed control. Technologists are predicting the eventual elimination of migrant labor requirements. Along Idth these reductions in costs. the returns per acre have increased as yields have approximately doubled since the period 1947-49. In recent years. this advance has been partially offset by 166 lower receipts per ton due to lower sugar content and purity of the beets. The lower quality of the beets has been attributed to less accurate topping by mechanical harvesters and high levels of nitrogen fertilizer application by growers. Resqupce ligitatigns.-—A study of resource requirements for sugar beet production indicates that the supply of well adapted soils is sufficient for a relatively large expansion of sugar beet acreage. However. the distribution of these soils with respect to present or potential factory locations. when the costs of transporting beets are considered. is likely to discourage large additional acreages in the Region. No other resource appears to be limiting. but their prices are expected to continue to rise. Ezgguctign.zespgnse.-An.inalysis of Eastern.Region production responses for sugar beets using linear programming with variable prices indicated that under reasonable projected prices. prospective technolo- gies and reasonable resource costs. sugar beets enqu a substantial competitive advantage over other typical crops. This implies that supplies of beets are likely to expand to the limit of present factory capacity. his large expansions in factory capacity are of questionable profitability (see below). sugar beet supplies are likely to be adequate for prospective processing capacity. These results are qualified by analysis of other factors influencing sugar beet production response. The evidence indicates that the costs of transporting beets to a factory or loading point is of major importance in determining whether the beets are to be included in the cropping system. Relative prices of sugar beets and other crops (particularly dry beans and corn) l6? and the presence of "fixed" specialized durables (trucks and har- ‘vesters) are also important determinants of production response. Other factors hypothesized to influence production response in sugar beets do not appear to be significant. Variability in total returns per harvested acre and proportion of acreage abandoned have both shown marked declines in recent.years. The degree of variability in returns to sugar beet production.is no greater than that for ccmpet- ing crops. Ergcessing of gugg; beets.-Sugar beet processing utilizes an expensive plant for a relatively short processing season. A year around staff is maintained for administration and inter-campaign maintenance and to aid farmers. This burden of overhead costs cannot be met unless a full volume of beets is available relative to process- ing capacity. The relatively large cost of transporting beets indicates that factories must be located in the midst of large bodies of adapted soils in order to achieve a satisfactory supply of beets. The decline in number of factories in.recent.years in the Eastern Region can largely be attributed to the inability of unfavorably located.plants to increase annual volume of beets processed in the face of stable sugar prices and rising costs of'materials and labor. Expansion of existing factory capacity appears to have feir potential in most,locations. Construction of new’plants would appear to be a questionable investment.in the Eastern.Region. even.in.the unlikely prospect of developing the necessary large supplies of beets at one location. 168 Marketing and demand.--he Eastern beet sugar industry supplies but a very small portion of the large East North Central sugar market. Producers in a deficit area would be expected to enjoy a considerable advantage. particularly for a product for which transportation costs are a significant factor. However. the freight advantage is at times offset in parts of the Eastern Region's market area by basis prices lower than that prevailing elsewhere in the nation. his price structure is a consequence of strong competition for the sweetener market among sugar suppliers from areas to the East. South and West. as well as from Midwestern corn sweetener producers. he cost of transporting refined sugar is sufficiently large that each region is partly isolated from the others. his permits a degree of price discrimination in the deficit Midwestern markets. As a consequence of the large number of suppliers in that market. the demand facing each individual seller is more elastic than that in his home area. Thus. the price in the Midwestern market is generally lower than elsewhere. he nature of the market for sugar is changing. Over half of all sugar supplies are now consumed by industrial users. Per capita direct domestic consumption is decreasing. Commercial users demand more varieties and grades and maintain more exact specifications for their purchases. Consumer packages now represent less than one third of the consumption. Some Eastern Region producers take advantage of a favorable acceptance of beet sugar by local consumers and market over half their output in consumer sized packages. This policy reduces some of the impacts of price and quality competition prevalent in the industrial grades. 169 Because of increased freight costs or from price concessions associated with penetrations of new markets. large scale expansion of output in the region would be likely to result in some reduction in net return per unit of sugar to both farmers and processors. These factors are of less importance than the competitive behavior of the large suppliers in the Midwestern market (given the level of sugar prices). Conclusions At this writing. the prospects for the beet sugar industry in the Eastern Region are not for either an immediate demise or for a period of rapid growth. Sugar beet growers.--The outlook for the next half decade for sugar beet growers appears to be a period of relatively favorable returns to beet production. A better than average price situation appears likely for at least the next few crops. Technological advances are reducing costs and.inconveniences and are eliminating variability of returns in‘beet production. There appears to be a strong likeli- hood that hybrid varieties will be available in commercial scale toward the end of this period. No comparable advantages are foreseen for the principal competing crops in the region. Thus. it appears that the crop will become more appealing to farmers who have not previously grown.beets. The resulting increases in output are not expected to be large relative to present and prospective processing capacity. \ Sugar beet p;ocesso;s.--Recent years have brought higher costs for nearly all purchased inputs. labor. equipment and fuel. Competitive 170 conditions and goverment policy have not permitted equivalent increases in sugar prices. These problems are compounded by the adverse trend in the quality of the beets received in recent years. Offsetting factors for processors are the expected period of relatively favorable prices and the likelihood of increasing supplies of beets to enable more effective utilization of capacity. Possibilities appear to exist for continued moderate expansion of plant capacity and modermzation of factories in the more favored locations. The feasibility of making a large increase in capacity by con- struction of new plant facilities turns on a number of points. Even at full capacity for a large scale factory. a significant improvement in the quality of the beets would be required to attain returns sufficient to justify the investment. Furthermore. it is doubtful that such large supplies of. beets could be acquired at any location in the region with- out the elimination of operations at one or more of the present plant sites. Given the pattern of distribution of favorably adapted soils and the relatively lesser cost per unit of capacity of expanding exist- ing plants. it appears that new plant construction would not be economically feasible. BIBIIOCRAPHY Books Bernhardt. Joshua. The Sugar Industry: and the Federal @vernmen . Washington. D.C.. 1948. Sugar Statistics Service. Boulding. K. E.. Ecgnomic Analysis. 3rd ed.. New York: Harper Bros.. 1955' Brandes. E. W.. and Coons. G. H.. "Climactic Relations of Sugar Cane and Sugar Beet.” U.S.D.A.. Yearbook 9f agriculture. 191+l. Washington. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 1941. Chilton. Cecil. ed.. Cgst Esmtion in the Process Indusges. New York: McGraw-Hill. l9 0. Cottrell. R. H.. Beet Sugar Ecgnomics. Caldwell. Idaho: Caxton Printers. 1952. Dalton. John E.. Sugar. A Case Stugy in vaernment Contrgl. New York: I'IacMillan & Co.. 1937. Fair. M. I... and mlliams. E. W.. Ecgnflcs g; kanspgrtag'gn. Revised ed.. New York: Harper Bros.. 1959. Heady. E. 0.. et. al.. A cultural Ad ustment Prob ems n a o Econom. Ames. Iowa: Iowa State College Press. 1958. . "Uses and Concepts in Supply Analysis." in Heady. E. 0.. ___2let- .. 6018-. MW; Ames. Iowa: Iowa State Univ.. 19 1. . and Candler. W.. gear Pregammigg News. Ames. Iowa: Iowa State Univ. Press. 1958. Johnson. G. 1... "Supply Functions-«Some Facts and Notions." in Heady. E. 0.. et. al.. monitural Adjustment Emblems in a Grow- W Ames. Iowa: Iowa State University Press. 1958. McGinnis. R. A.. ed. . Beet Sugar Technglgg. New York: Reinhold Pub- lishing Corp.. 1951. McKee. Dean E.. and Loftsgard. L. D.. ”Programming Intra-Farm Normative Supply Functions." in Heady. E. 0.. et. al.. eds.. Agricultural Supply Functigns. Ames. Iowa: Iowa State Univ. Press. 19 l. 172 173 Highell. R. L. and Black. John D.. Interreg’onal Competition in Amculture. Cambridge. Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press. 1951. Turner. Jack T.. Marketing of SugarJ Homeweod. 111.: Richard D. Imn. Inc.. 19330 Wolf. H. A.. The U.S. Sugar Pglig and Its Mot 9n Cuba. Doctoral dissertation. Ann Arbor. Mich.: Univ. of Mich. microfilms. 1958 . U.S. Beet Sugar Association. The Beet Sugar Sign. U.S. Beet Sugar Assoc.. Wash. D.C.. 1959. Van Hook. Andrew. Sugar. Its PrgductignI Technolog and Uses. New York: the Ronald Press. Co.. 1949. mlson. G. Lloyd. flgilggad fieight Rate Stacture. Traffic Service Corp.. waShe D.C.. 1951c U.S. Government Publications Ballinger. Roy A. and Larkin. L. G.. Sweeteners Used m the Cannigg Indus ° Thei Com etitive Position n the United States. A.E.R. - 20. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. l9 3. Jackson. Donald. Econ mics of S ar Beet Marketi E.R.S. - 49. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. 1932. . et. al.. Marketin 5 ar Beets. A.M.S. - 137. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. 1953. Jones. P. E.. and Thomason. F. G.. Competigve Reggons Amogg Suga; and 99:3 Sweeteners. Ag. Info. Bull. No. 148. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. P.M.A.. 1951. Kinsley. R. T.. Case Stugz Data; ‘o'n‘firoducjivity arflfiacgggz Performance: Beet Sugar Refmirng. B.L.S.. Report No. 3. Wash. D.C.: U.S. Labor Dep't. 1953. Lax-kin. L. 0.. Farm and Retail Pricesjgr Beet Sugar. A.M.S. - 421:. Wash. DeCe: UeSeDeAe. Aet‘leSe. 19600 . and Updike. Alma. Metigg Harm fgr Sugar. Marketing ResearCh Report 31].. Wash. DeCe: UeSeDeAe. AeMcSe' 1959e Lill. J. G.. Su ar Beet cum the N rth Central States. Farmer's Bull. No. 20 0. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. 1954. Oviatt. C. R.. "Sixty Years in Sugar." Sugar Repgrts. No. 128. U.S.D.A.. A.S.C.S.. 1962. 174 Poats. Frederick J.. Marketigg Liggid Sugar. Wash. D.C.: U.S.D.A.. 1953. U.S.D.A.. Agricultural Marketing Service. Nglasses Market NewsI Annual 3%”. 1262. Ael‘IeSe - 79. WaShington. D.C.. 19 20 . Agricultural Marketing Service. Sugar Beets 1224-1952. wash. D.C.. 1954. . Agricultural Research Service. Su Rese h f the U.S.D.A. and Qggperatigg Agencies. Wash. D.C.. 1932. . Economic Research Service. Econgmics of Sugarbeet Marketing. 3.1110 NOe “’9. Wash. De Ce. 1962e I . Sugar Division. Beet Sugar Factogies in the U.S.. wash. D.C.. 1961. . Sugar Division. "Relationships Between Sugar Prices and Sugar Beet Plantings." Sugar Repeats 10;. Wash. D.C.. 1960. . Sugar Division. Sugg; Egpgrts (monthly). Wash. D.C. . Sugar Division. Sugar Statistics and figlated Data. vol. I. wash. D.C.. 1961. . Sugar Division. Suga; Statistics and Related Data. vol. II. Wash. DeCe 9 1959e . Sugar Division. Sugg; Act of 124§ as Amended. Wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 19 2. . Sugar Division. Sugar Determination 851.1. Amendment 3. Committment of Natigyg; §gg§g Beet.Acreage Reserve. 1262 and Subsequent C2925. Reprinted in Federal Register. March 5. 1963. . Sugar Division. Sugar Detegginatigg 862.3I wages Rates: Sggar Beets. Reprinted in Federal Register. April 24. 19 3. . Sugar Division. "The U.S. Sugar Program." Sugar Repgg . NO. 1214’. waShe DeCe. 1962e . Statistical Reporting Service. Annual 9:92 Summagy. 1962. Wash. D.C.. 1962. U.S. House of Representatives. 53rd Congress. 2nd Session. Tagiff Heagiggs befgze the Committee on way§ and.Means. Document No. 43. wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 1893. . 55th Congress. 2nd Session. Document No. 396. Spgoial Repgrt on the Beet Sggar Industgy. wash. D.C.. Gov't Printing Office. 189 e 175 . 87th Congress. 2nd Session. Qggflerence 3629;; 9;; Suga; Act Amendments gf 126 . House Report No. 1957. Wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 1962. . 87th Congress. 2nd Session. Committee on Agriculture. History and Qperagons 9f the U.S. Sugar flagram. Wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 19 2. . 87th Congress. lst Session. Committee on Agriculture. S e 3:.ng 9n Sggar. Wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. Feb. 14. l l. U.S. Tariff Commission. Report to the Ezesident 9n Sugar. Report No. 73. Wash. D.C.: Gov't Printing Office. 1934. Articles and Periodicals Anderson. R. N.. "Progress and Problems in Sugar Beet Weed Control." Qastal—ized Facts About Sugar. Amer. Crystal Sugar Co.. Vol. XVI. No. 1. Denver. Colo.. l9 2. Baker. T.‘W.. Haskell. D. R. and Resch. I. A.. "Factory Treatment of Process liquors Using Activated Carbon in a Continuous Process to Improve Sugar Quality." Part I. II. S ar A unar May. June. 1961. Vol. 56. No. 5 (monthly). Baltimore. Md. Barmington. R. B.. "What's Happening to Beet Drills." keggh the Leaves. Vol. L. No. 1. Great Western Sugar Co.. Denver. Colo.. 19 1. Cook. R. L.. Davis. J. F. and Frakes. M. 0.. 1958-60 Production Pracgces of Michigan Sugar Beet Farmers. Mich. Agr. EXP. Sta.. Quarterly Bull.. Art. 44-38. Feb. 19 2. Edwards. Clark. "Resource Fixity and Farm Organization." J .F.E.. Vol. 42. No. 4. Nov. 1960. Farmers and Manufacturers Beet Sugar Association. Sugg get J93 . (periodical) Saginaw. Michigan. Haddock. J. L.. et. al.. "me Influence of Cultural Practices on the Quality of Sugar Beets." Jgp;n_a; 9f the Amer. Sgc. of Sugar Beet Tech.. Vol. X.‘ No. 4. Jan.. 1959. "History of the Michigan Sugar Company. 1906-56." Pi neer News. Saginaw. Mich.. March-Aug.. 1956. Johnson. G. L.. "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis? J.F.E.. Vol. “'2. N00 2. Flay 1960e Lamborn Sugar-Market Re ort (weekly). Vol. KL. No. 45. Lamborn and Co.. New York. 19 2. 176 Mich. Dep't of Agr.. Micggan Afloultural Statispics. Lansing (annual). Moore. John R.."Economic Implications of Share Contracts for Sugar Beets. J.F.E.. Vol. XLIV. No. 2. 1962. University and Ebcperiment Station Publications Blosser. R. H.. Cost ofjroducing Crops in Northwestern Ohio. Research Bull. 923. Ohio Ag. EXP. Sta.. Wooster. Ohio. 1962. . Costs and Reggns from Su arbeets in Ohio. Bull. A.E. 334. Ohio Ag. Exp. Sta.. Wooster. Ohio. 1962. Davis. I. F. and Metzler. W. H.. Su ar Beet Labor in Northern Colorado. 0010. State Univ. Exp. Sta.. Tech. Bull. 63. Ft. Collins. 1958. Elterich. J.. Johnson. G. L.. and Call. David. PerSppctive on Michigan's Farm Labor Problems. Ag. Exp. Sta.. Mich. State Univ.. East Lansing. Mich.. 19 3. Hinton. R. A.. Improvipg Livestock. Labor and Capital Information for Farm Development and Management. Research Report No. 34. Ag. Econ. Dep't. Univ. of Ill.. 1960. . Some Original Sources 9; Selected Budgeting Information from the North Central StatesI 1245-52. Research Report No. 35. Agr. Econ. Dep't.. Univ. of Ill.. 1960. Johnson. C. E. and Wright. K. T.. Reducing Sugar Beet Costs. Michigan CirCUlar Mle 215, l'flChe Agr. PbCp. Stan. EaSt LanSlng. 19490 Lard. C. F.. Profitable Reorganization of Representative Fame in Lower Michigan and Northeastern Indiana with Special Emphasis on Feed Grains and Livestock. unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. Mich. State UniVe. EaSt LanSing. 33110110. 19630 Michigan State University Cooperative Extension Service. Extension Bull. E-159. Feptilizer Recommendations for Micppgan Caps. 1963. Schuh. G. E.. fps Sppply pf 1‘11}; in the Detrpit Milk Shed as Affected 91 Cost of Producgon. Mich. Agr. Exp. Sta. Tech. Bull. 259. 1957. Tinley. J. M.. Economic Factors Affecting the Sugar Beet Ipdustgz. Calif. Agr. Exp. Sta. Ser.. Circular 413. Univ. of Wise" Agr. Exp. Sta.. Bulletin 544. Sega of North Central Begon. 1960. Wright. K. T.. Sugar Beet Cpsts and Returns. Special Bull. 305. Ag. Exp. Sta. Mich. State Univ.. East Lansing. Mich.. 1940. 177 Other Sources Bauserman. H. M.. Denver. Colorado. personal communications, April 1. 1963 and May 24. 1963. Brooke. M. David. Marginal Productivities offiIanuts or; Cash Crop Farms in the Thumb and Sa na Valle Area of Mic an. unpublished M.S. thesis. Michigan State University. 1958. Cottrell. R. H.. S eech delivered to meetin 0 California Beet Su ar Technologists. Feb. 21. 1959 (unpublished mimeo). Folken. Herbert G.. personal communicapipn. July 25. 1962. Program Analysis Branch. Sugar Division. U.S.D.A. Food and Agricultural Organization. United Nations. Production Yeapbook. 1261. Rome. Italy. 1961. Fbod and Agricultural Organization. United Nations. prld Sugar Ecopppy in.§igppes. 1880-1959. Rome. Italy. 1961. Frakes. M. G.. et. al.. How to Grog Sugar Beets With Np Labor. Anerican Society of Sugar Beet Technologists. Pppceedings. East Lansing. Mich.. 1961. Kweskin. S. R.. (Lamborn and Co.. Sugar Brokers. Saginaw. Mich.). Marketipg Mic an Beet Su ar Speech at Sugar Beet Day. Mich. State Univ.. Jan. 28. 1958 (processed). Michigan weather Service and U.S.‘Wgather Bureau. Cooperating. Climate pf MichiganI p1 Stations. East Lansing. Mich.. 1963. Perreault. R. P.. The Acreage Resppnse pf'Micpigan.Fagpers in.East Central Counties to the Relative Ppices of Sugap Beets and Field Beans. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. Dep't of Ag. Econ.. Mich. State Univ.. 1956. Pierce. L. T.. State climatologist for Ohio. Columbus. Ohio. personal cpppunicapion. June 13. 1963. Polopolus. Leonidas. Spppcpppp and Pepgppmapce pf the United States Beet S a ndus Unde Federal otection and Control. unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. Univ. of Calif.. Berkeley. 19 0. Snyder. F. N.. "The Influence of Nitrogen Fertilizer on Yield and Sucrose." American Society of Sugar Beet Technolo sts. Proccedin s of the Twelfth Eastern Regional Meeting. 1963 forthcoming). U.S. Beet Sugar Association (Compilers). Beet Sugar Contracts. 1962. Washington. DeCe. 19620 178 Viton. A. and Pignalosa. F.. Ipends and Pposgcts 1.9 World Sugar Cpnsump- tipn. monthly bull. Agr. Econ. and Statistics. Vol. IX. Nos. 1 and 2. F.A.O.. Rome. Italy. 1960. Walker. Dr. Francis. personal communication. Dep't. of Ag. Econ.. Ohio State Univ.. Oct. 30. 1962. Western Beet Sugar Producers. Inc.. Beet Su ar Handbook. San Francisco. Calif.. 1961. APPENDIX I canouomcxcu. HISTORY or BEET 30cm rue roams IN THE mm REGION]- Early Trials: 18;§-;822 White Pigeon. Inch. 1838-40 Black Hawk. Wise. 1870-75 Fond du Lac. mac. 1866-70 Freeport. Ill. 1871-72 Chatsworth. Ill. 1866-71 15221 MENOMONEE FALLS. WISC. Erected by Visconsin Sugar Co. Capacity. 500 tons. Dismantled in 1932. Eli BAY CITY. I'DZCH. Erected by Michigan Sugar Co. Capacity. 500 tons. Machinery moved to Waverly. Iowa. in 1907. 1.829. ALMA. MECH. Erected by Alma Sugar Co. Original capacity. 600 tons. Dismantled by Michigan Sugar Co. in 1959. BAY CITY. MCH. Erected by Bay City Sugar Co. Capacity. 600 tons. Dismantled by Michigan Sugar Co. in 1941. BENTON HARBOR. MICH. Erected by Wolverine Sugar Co. Capacity 350 tons. Machinery moved to Kitchener. Ontario. in 1902. C539. MICH. Erected by Peninsular Sugar Refining Co. Original capacity. 00 tons 5nd present capacity. 1.450 tons. Present owner. Michigan Sugar COe HOLLAND. MICH. Erected by Holland Sugar Co. Original capacity. 350 tons. Dismantled by Lake Shore Sugar Co. in 1952. KALAMAZOO. MICH. Erected by Kalamazoo Beet Sugar Co. Capacity. 500 tons. Machinery moved to Madison. Wisconsin. in 1905. WEST BAY CITY. MICH. Erected by West Bay City Sugar Co. Original capacity. 500 tons. Dismantled by West Bay City Sugar Co. in 1943. lSource: U.S.D.A.. Commodity Stabilization Service. Best Suga; Factories in the U.S.. Washington. D.C.. 1961. 2Underlining indicates factory in operation for the 1963 season. 18Q 181 129.9 MARINE CITY. MICH. Erected by Marine Sugar Co. Capacity. 350 tons. Dismantled in 1928. FRDIONT. OHIQ. Erected by Continental Sugar Co. Original capacity. 350 tons and present capacity. 1.300 tons. Present owner. Northern Ohio Sugar Co. 1201 BAY CITY (SALZEJRG). MICH. Erected by German-American Sugar Compamr. Original capacity. 400 tons and present capacity. 3.200 tons. Present owner. Monitor Sugar Division of Robert Gage Coal Comparw. LANSING. MICH. Erected by Lansing Sugar Co. Original capacity. 800 tons. Dismantled by Michigan Sugar Co. in 1953. SAGINAW. MICH. Erected by Saginaw Sugar Co. Capacity. 600 tons. Machinery moved to Sterling. Colorado. in 1905. 1202 CARROLLTQN (SAGINAW‘Q. EOE. Erected by Saginaw Valley Sugar Comparw. Original capacity. 00 tons and present capacity. 1.500 tons. Present owner. Michigan Sugar Co. %$}~IEI.L. MICE. Erected by Sanilac Sugar Refining Co. Original capacity 00 tons and present capacity. 1.100 tons. Present owner Michigan Sugar Co. MT. CLEMENS. TECH. Erected by Macomb Sugar Co. Original capacity. 600 tons. Dismantled by Franklin County Sugar Co. in 1951. SWING MICH. Erected by Sebewaing Sugar Refining Co. Original capacity. 00 tons and present capacity. 1. 500 tons. Present owner. Michigan Sugar Co. 1292 EAST TAWAS. MICH. Erected by Tawas Sugar Co. Capacity. 600 tons. Machinery moved to Chaska. Minn.. in 1906. means. HIGH. Erected by Menominee River Sugar Co. Original capacity. 1.000 tons. Dismantled by Menominee Sugar Co. in 1955. W0. MICH. Erected by Owosso Sugar Co. Original capacity. 1.000 tons. Dismantled by Michigan Sugar Co. in 1948. ST. LOUIS. MICH. Erected by St. Louis Sugar Co. Original capacity. 500 tons. Dismantled by Lake Shore Sugar Co. in 1955. 182 1204 CHIPPEWA FALLS. WISC. Erected by Chippewa Sugar Refining Co. Machinery moved from Kalamazoo. Mich. Dismantled in 1934. JANESVILLE. WISC. Erected by Rock County Sugar Co. Machinery originally erected at Dresden. Ontario. in 1902. Capacity. 600 tons. Moved to Quebec in 1941. 1295. RIVERDALE. ILL. Erected by Charles Pope. Operated in 1926. dismantled later. possibly 1927. BLISSFIELD. MICH. Erected by Continental Sugar Co. Original capacity. 600 tons. Dismantled by Northern Ohio Sugar Co. in 1957. MADISON. WISC. Erected by United States Sugar Co. Machinery moved from Rochester. Mich. Capacity. 600 tons. Dismantled.in 1924. 1206 CHARLEVOIX. MICH. Erected by west Michigan.Sugar Co. Capacity. 600 tons. Machinery moved to Ottawa. Ohio. in 1912. 1219. PAULDING. OHIO. Erected by German-American.Sugar Co. Original capacity. 700 tons. Dismantled by Great Lakes Sugar Co. in.1952. (Present owner. Paulding Sugar Co.. has announced intentions of reopening this plant in 1964 or 1965.) 1211 ELNDLAY. OHIQ. Erected by Continental Sugar Co. Original capacity. 600 tons and present capacity. 1.250 tons. Present owner. Northern Ohio Sugar CO e 1212 OTTAWA. OHIO. Erected by Ohio Sugar Co. Machinery originally erected at Charlevoix. Mich.. in 1906. Original capacity. 600 tons and present capacity. 1.400 tons. Present owner. Buckeye Sugar. Inc. TOLEDO. OHIO. Erected by Toledo Sugar Co. Capacity. 1.000 tons. Dis- mantled in 1941. 1220 MT. PLEASANT. MICH. Erected by Columbia Sugar Co. Original capacity. 1.200 tons. Dismantled by Michigan Sugar Co. in 1951. 183 GREEN BAY. WISC. Erected by Green Bay Sugar Co. Original capacity. 600 tons. Present owner. Menominee Sugar Co. (Ceased operations after 1961 season.) APPENDIX II 185 .muooaoom .oom .oz Adam .ooom .HH .Ho> .opcoShwm ucoscaobom moosaocH\m .modmmd msoaam> .mp 0 mm no am one .mmmH upon reorder use we mauopm as m ..m.m.o ..<.Q.m.o “coasom\m sea.ma 10.1ma em.na m ma mom m.n~ m mm m.mo o.mo mmm.m coma mom.oa mo.mma Ho.aa n.ma mmm.a H.Nm m.om 0.1m H.ma Nom.m mmma omm.oa Hm.mom mo.ma m.ma NHH.H m.a~ o.~m o.am m.mm emm.m mmma ema.ma om.maa mm.ma o.ma mom m.o~ c.1m 0.0m n.1m moo.m mama mmm.o~ ma.moa mo.ma o.HH emo m.ma a.om o.mo m.me omn.m enma 1mm.aa mm.wma mm.ma m.oH new m.ma m.om H.oe o.mo mmm.m mmma «mm.m mo.moa mm.ma o.NH Hmm «.ma m.mm «.1e 0.0a mmm.o omma mam.m No.0ma mm.mH m.HH can m.HH o.mm m.o: m.mm som.m mama mem.m mm.mea ww.ma m.oa mmn m.NH o.mw m.mo o.mm omm.n mmma mmo.m Eamon“ mail” M12” mom “in mém inn m.mw 36.3 Han omo.oa mm.moa ma.oa a.oa omo.a m.ma m.om m.am m.a~a oom.m onma mmm.oa mm.mma o~.oa m.m mom m.aa m.mm 0.0m m.om nmm.o mama moo.m mm.moa m~.ea m.m an: 1.0H o.~w H.Nm ~.mo mmm.o mama moa.m o1.moa mo.ea a.e woo o.oa «.mm o.ee m.mm ome.e mama Hmm.ma ma.aoa Ho.ea m.m 1am N.HH ~.om m.mm e.moa mam.m coma ooa.m am.maa om.ma a.m mmo H.m 0.1m o.am o.mm mmo.m mama owo.m oo.oma mm.oa m.m own m.m m.mm «.mm «.mo mma.m mama Hmo.o om.mm om.ma m.e mmm m.m m.mm o.mo m.mm woo.o mama mmm.oa m~.mm mo.oa w.m mmo.H m.m m.ma m.HHH o.ooH mmo.ma mama mam.m so.mm mH.m m.oa oHo.H m.m m.mm m.mm o.ooa mmm.oa Homa omn.m No.1a mH.m H.m .Nmo.a m.m o.am «.maa m.~ma enm.NH coma mmo.m mm.mo Ho.m o.m mmo.H m.m m.nm H.0NH m.m~a mmo.ma mama ...n.. u..... ----u N.@ moo.a m.m m.mm o.NNH o.ama mmm.ma mmma ---uu- -....- ---n- m.m mom 1.a H.mm m.ea m.mm mmm.oa amma .qOmwm cm .m woos .9 oooa moooa oomwm ous>uoao< nomumpCo mm mood mm am Hymn m” mm mm ed mopmobuoopcmamum mm A Show a osoocH“ sea a oflofiw A poem" moped ” oopcmam a sham homeoaodn Ho « a fleece“ mocha » pom u .>< «umwdmu .Amm « mowm “emerged“ «nonadzu meow one \H OH u . m " .dw “ am 1 ,.e n u o u m u N u H « \melmmmH .zom moosaocH\m .mosmmw msoaae> .mp 0 mm he on use .mmma .mumzhnom .edN .oz .Hasm .pmpm .HH .Ho> .epma copeaom use medpmfipepm am am ..m.m.o ..<.n.m.D "condom\m 186 mom.a oe.oo~ oa.ma e.oa mum m.om m.em o.- m.m~ Ham coma mao.m oo.oaa mm.oa o.ea 1mm m.HN m.om m.am m.~m omo.H mmma 000.: mm.mma oa.ma H.1a mom m.ma m.om m.HN H.mm Hoa.a mama ome.m mm.mma mm.ma m.ma mew m.ma o.wm m.am m.~m oeH.H mmma mmm.~ mm.mma mo.ma ~.~H mma o.ea m.em m.oa m.ma mao.a emma mom.m om.mmH mm.aa m.mH mam m.na m.~m o.ma o.ma oeH.H nmma oam.~ mo.1ma oo.HH N.oa mom m.ma 1.1m N.ma o.ma ooa.a omma moo.~ mm.oma mo.oa o.mH mma H.NH a.ow m.ma m.ma NmH.H mmmfl moo.~ mm.mea m~.ma H.HH and o.aa m.wm m.HH o.mH oHo.H Nmma mmm.a . om.HmH ma.ma o.oa mma m.HH «.mm a.~a 1.1H moo.a Hmma Nam.m mm.mma mm.ma o.~a aam N.oa m.ma o.mm m.om mma.m onma mmm.m mm.eoa mm.ma m.oa mmm m.oa m.mm m.mm m.om mmm.m mama ooo.m mo.mma mm.oa m.NH Hoe m.m m.om o.ma 1.1H amm.a mama aim ding 8.3 «a. and mm now new mom 18$. mama mem.m mo.moa mo.eH o.m mum m.m m.mm e.mm m.mm mmo.~ mama ooo.m eo.moH no.1a m.m mom m.m m.am m.om m.m~ oas.~ mama Hmo.a mo.oma He.oa m.m mHH 1.0 o.mm e.ma o.ma amm.a mama moo.a oe.mm om.oa H.e om o.m n.1m o.aa o.am QNH.~ mama mmm.n mN.HHH am.m o.~a mmm m.m m.mm m.ao H.Hm oom.o mama aow.m mo.moa mm.m H.HH ma: m.m m.mm o.mm m.oo moH.o Home Ham.m om.Hm mm.m ~.m 1am H.m H.Hm m.oo m.oo Hmo.o coma mam.m mm.oe em.m m.m mom m.m o.am m.oo o.Hm mao.m mmma -u - -..u- N.m mom o.oa o.em m.om m.mm omo.m mmma -..n- m.m 11H m.m m.mm m.1m m.mm moa.m amma ooo.aw .m .m woos mooe qmo.a moooa ooo.H ous> a ” mecca " o 04 u eon 1‘“ u a “ msaem a . mom « them a com a poem “ com “ monod « them “ oweoao4 A me A Show » osoocH “ com. A macaw « hmmcm “ moped u oopcmam « smocked « a 962.32 « Meow mono Hopes ” among a com A .>< ” “ .amm « Hole “ a u “ hagaua—u-mammmmwu:.mw « a“ c e u .m u o u m “ «gm-m-nnnm. “ % f i t z i * ‘1‘ ll l'lll'll'... 'l‘l'l'.u I'I..|| .l‘l II’I \maolmmma .OHmo .moHBmHagHm ZOHHUDDomm swam Mdoom amaomqmm .N mqmds Nanzmmm< 187 .noppms cMHonom poo anon on moHon axoon no moooHo cH moanwon on has Amos noV cos HmQOHpHUo<\m mxosnp oe0H\mcop m o8 to 3.3 "32 sooooo no n no N m .8 m .33 ode S .. dam .. once nod oo.omw. "open sepmgo nopomnp nopmo>nmn use» mH «oHoHH o.N H sOHQIm son H omosnem = .mcHuHmz \m oHHcs no>Hnr moon» no nova Inomo novmosnem he moon on on noQQOp m .>oz mosdmmm .momnmno once: sea oz on. = Inopmom mo>eoH who poem ImN .umom .36 once nod om.:w on. = so: near Ions» or. = me NH I opeprHdo mesh . sons 23 pom 8.2 mm. .183 153-83 :2» Ban .. 0:. H = $3 NH I onwardvgo : once cowoan: Horace mom or. H = a mmonoIoon cowoanz Inez cOHHew nod 499 is} a Bo 1585 aim mcHepsoo evanescence mendm .2322 e .odom N .. one Harpoocm use «pa “mango .mocppe Apcownoso I .pnom OHIomIm $000 I *\ nopocnu hence spa: Ionav hence econ .baa 004w @.ooom_snomocoz am.H on. H .BOHaIN HHHno Md one ouHHHpnom .pceHm IHHnd< ochon_3onndm ofimo fie. £8» 32% mom Sofia. engages mm. H .. .m ..omoadu moflfiaménm Aroma nopomnp .poo mm. a sodium :31 :on ...ooom u one no a u a a come A « mxnmeom use mHeHnopeE » endow com A comm“ nosed “ nWHoaHmo « COHucnomo no pcosmfidvm a moped wme .OHmo ammzmamcz 92¢ z¢0Hm0HE mmzoq ZMMHmdm mo mHHom Qmm quH .mamum mdmsm mom mmu¢.mmm mBDAZH_nz¢ mchademo .m mqmde xHszmm< 188 ua0H\.an ca gun: moHHa m mm. H maHHsmm mm .m:< mH ...Eom .pao mH “uHaHn m. m.H mm .OH oanSoo mm .wsH mH .pmmm 3. H .. .m 8H2 .mev oEméonEH: mm .mé nopoanp mH .poom on. H ERIN mm $33 3. .33 H ...Eom nopaH nHHENm o.H wchmogo 0H .m:« OH ana noan hHHSdh o.N wnHoon Pam H 23» 0H anu om. H = m: HNIcOHua>HpHso H cash NH 056 om. H = m: noooozéoflwzpdzo m 05.6 oH aqua oHIONIm Hoom .umom .mnH mm on. H g m: pqum mm nag AHn.H nopoanp "mmzn ..m.ov deHn3ws hwnmm cm. H konIN m: mango pgoanSoIonm has has mm. H = .m gonna: a meu ..oonm HHom HHno< nopounp ad: om. H .30Hmam =HHIm :OHm HHnm< mxnweom on.» meHnopmz mwmwm WWW nos nozom MWHMMHmMU mafianomo no pcoagwm $va mo mAHom 9mm mg £56m maqum Nan Mom mmod mam EDmZH 924 mZOHHSHmmo oomH .ono Hmmzmnmoz n24 ZHGHHUHE .d as NHszmmd .ommo mHsp cH ooHnm no: Bonn ooposooo pmoo .oHom HH hHao voHHoam on on UQSSmmw mH snoo nwm\w 189 nopownp on. sonIN onopm and stm = oHno ..sn OHH nopomnp H .ooa cdenon ..dn 00H "vHoHM mm.H H .30HmIm mH \mficnoo nwov pmo>nwm OH .900 Mm oHso .mnop n.mH nopoonu no3oHn .mcommz N c8232 .88. mH .329 om.m H 338m om.HHm 28.. vs. 9% _. hJHowmwo ndon\BNH .vaon mono.30n\= nopomnu nommono pmo>nwg omanom HHoam_3on H om.H H 3onIm .nn\e NH owonom I AommHHmv pwo>nmm .pmmm mm coda om. H __ ms Hm I 33330 0H 3. mcst QI¢.N mm. 0:. H = .wH hdnmm OMIH ocdu mH opwanc Edflzossw $OOH 0%. H = m& sz moono oon IH 0:55 nopownp MN Adm GHANA “H83 88 .3 m. 3. H 33?... m: wcfiqum H .82 , E.. on. H .. .m MN .623 H. x5. .88 HHom H23 nopoanv Adm om. H 339$ EHA :on Hg: “ u u u h, u u g... a... . .. . . .... a. . .WHMM. . ...... - a... . .2. wmmH .OHmo Hmmzmemoz QZd ZdUHmoHE zmmamdm mo mAHom 0mm Mada .Aszmm mo mo4HHm momv zmoo mom mmo<.mmm mHDQZH 924 mZOHadmmmo .m mqde Nanzmmmd 190 nonconp m3. H BonIN comm: Hdmm .. oHno :H .52 no oanaoo wH fimEoE 5“ .3 mm “33» m3. H I mm .OH 3.2.x -m 32. A.p:doooa «.3.de 3 8320 8.3 30.8.3 $33. 98.8 o... HEM... om: © doom .3 z 5.3 .mom 3. H sonIN HHHnHv .m cmmoanq mmonoImoe IH .nmz oHIomIOH Macon nopodnu. mm H..... 33 3. H 33.3 HHHnHV .m 333.8“ .m £25 ..mH show .ooanvon quonm nopownu om .pmom on "unwop novmo on on UoEdmm< on. H 3onIm .m xN I_Bonnw: w men ImH .Mdd « ono< nom ” u “ mmwwmmmo " « oanaom and deHnooaz ” mndom » no: “ nozom “ no oNHm u noprnomo no pcosdevm « mopan agenda .mo aHom. Qmm as .949; EZHZ Mom 954 mam manna/NH 94¢ mzofimdmmmo mmmH .OHmo Haamoz azd 73mg”? .0 as NHQEmmd 191 nopoonp 0H .m54 3. H onoIm meow... Hag om 33. 020 :3 on 0H .o3. caoflofi :3 oo .33» 3. H II mm .OH 325% cm 62. nopoonp .3) 6:3. QJIN on. H 33.7... .NH bran 82. doom awn nepoonp 3.84: .38. 3. H :OHQIN .o ..HHflnon on. 2.: H29... novoonp sonnon R. H .SHoIm .33 .m H... I ooflHHn H203 nopoonp om. H .SHoIm 3H x m .58 H23. u onod nom “ » nuHooooo “ « oxnosom woo oHoHnopoz u onsom com.” 2oz ” nozom no ouHm u noHponomo no psoamHsvm» oopon . oooH .38 93.5952 024 zoo.o poomom add. moon mm.H “oHoHH om.H N .. onopo coo Hdom .. c3 So .3 353 mm. H .. onm .. 3. H = .w 33m .. mm. H .. K. :02 33. own H.230... 1.8m nBoofi momm Hospoo wow 3. H onmIN .m oNHHHpnoh .3an onHonmmfiMWo©omomHmnome .ooHnmn3co :fionw HHoEo 3 oomnono €on HHnEH. ocoowmoowwwpoz Mama“ . 2oz . noenonH mwflwlmwd aofionomo no psoagwm oopon mme .030 E35352 924 z¢on0Hz 559$ mo mHHom Qmm m3 .MSH H3443 mafia Mom 984 mam EEZH 924. mzoflgmo .m mama finzmmmd. "I1mm@mgwmrujanwzfimifl‘n“