THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL. TESTS OF PORTFOLIOS SELECTED FROM STOCKS WITH POOR PAST PERFORMANCE AND AN INVESTIGATION OF THE ABILITY OF DISCRIMINANT ANALYSIS TO DIFFERENTIATE PERFORMANCE mmtion to: the Game of Ph. D. MIOHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY WAYNE FAIRBURN 1,975 '4; c“; ESTIGATION OF THE ABILITY 0F DISCRIMINANT ANALYSIS T0 DIFFERENTIATE PERFORMANCE pfiertte: by ‘-‘_ 7 .‘- § ;- Whilllipiiburn V J ‘9 .. i...» has been‘éccepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Business - Finance degree in J.» ‘ kA-AA4 0 .l‘. ‘ Major profmx -‘ .. III 2 I II III III III \I\3 II 3 III ABSTRACT THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL, TESTS OF PORTFOLIOS SELECTED FROM STOCKS WITH POOR PAST PERFORMANCE AND AN INVESTIGATION OF THE ABILITY 0F DISCRIMINANT ANALYSIS TO DIFFERENTIATE PERFORMANCE by Nayne Fairburn The purpose of this research was twofold.’ The first purpose was to test the Sharpe-Lintner capital asset pricing model (CAPM), on the sample of common stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange which had the poorest price performance during various calendar years. The second purpose was to ascertain whether multiple discriminant analysis could predict future relative performance ranks of a similar sample of securities based upon a profile of their financial characteristics. The initial sample for the CAPM tests consisted of those twenty common stocks which had experienced the greatest percentage price losses during each of the calendar years 1956 through 1967. Those firms without calendar year accounting periods as well as utilities, financial institutions, and transportation companies, were excluded from the initial sample. The test of the CAPM entailed the comparison of realized one-year and three-year holding period returns (exclusive of cash dividends) subsequent to the year of poor price performance, with returns condi- tionally expected by the CAPM, given the market return over the holding wayne Fairburn periods and given the historically calculated beta coefficients. Twelve portfolios with one-year holding periods and ten portfolios over three- year holding periods were tested. The paired difference t-test of the null hypothesis that the average differences between realized returns and those conditionally expected by the CAPM was not significantly different from zero, was not rejected at the .05 level. The Sharpe-Lintner CAPM gave conditionally expected return predictions which over the ten year period tested did not differ on average from.the realized returns. However, it was found that within individual one-year and three-year holding periods, large differences between realized and conditionally expected returns typically occurred. The tests of the ability of discriminant analysis to differentiate investment performance involved using the same sample of firms as for the CAPM'tests, selected in the same manner, but for the calendar years 1962 through 1971. The tests were divided into two parts. The first series of tests concerned the ability of the discriminant functions to correctly classify according to performance in nine-month and thirty- three month holding periods (beginning in April subsequent to each calendar year of poor price performance), a random holdout sample of firms from.the same time period as that from.which the discriminant functions were calculated. This test determined whether the discriminant functions could detect variable profile relationships which were stable within the same time period. Each discriminant function was constructed from a profile of fourteen representative financial characteristics. The next series of tests evaluated the predictive ability of wayne Fairburn discriminant analysis by using the functions developed during the period 1962-1966 to classify firms from the later period 1967-1971 according to expected relative performance. The estimated performance rankings were compared with the actual performance rankings for this later period and correlated using the Spearman Rank Order Correlation Coefficient. The null hypothesis for both test series was that the correlation between actual and predictedperformance ranks was less than or equal to zero and the alternative hypothesis that it was greater than zero. None of the tests rejected the null hypothesis. The results uniformly indicated that for the sample and time period tested, discriminant analysis possessed little ability to differentiate performance among securities either within the same time period or for future time periods as would be implied by the use of discriminant analysis for investment purposes. THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL, TESTS OF PORTFOLIOS SELECTED FROM STOCKS WITH POOR PAST PERFORMANCE AND AN INVESTIGATION OF THE ACILITY OF DISCRIMINANT ANALYSIS TO DIFFERENTIATE PERFORMANCE By‘x“ .\ ‘\Lk Wayne-Fairburn A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Financial Administration 1975 To Bea ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I wish to express deep and sincere appreciation to my disserta- tion committee members: Dr. Myles Delano, Dr. Alden Olson, and Dr. Dan Collins. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page AcmommSo O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 iii LIST OF TABLES O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O C v Chapter I INTRODUflION O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 1 Capital Market Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Multiple Discriminant Analysis. . . . . . . . . . 5 ReseaICh Purpose. 0 O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O 9 outlineOfTeStSoooooooooooooooo. 10 Capital Asset Pricing Model Tests . . . . . . . 10 Discriminant Analysis Tests . . . . . . . . . . 11 II LITRATURE REVIEW 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O 15 Sharpe-Lintner Model. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Discriminant Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 FiflflDCial Ratios. O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 19 III “momLOGY O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 25 Test of the Capital Asset Pricing Model . . . . . 25 Discriminant Analysis Tests . . . . . . . . . . . 32 Sample and Data Items . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35 Test Procedures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 Iv RESULTS 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 44 Capital Asset Pricing Model Test Results. . . . . 44 Discriminant Analysis Tests Results . . . . . . . 48 v CONCLUSIONS 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 55 APPENDIX 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 59 BIBLIOGRAPHY O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O O 64 iv Table 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 LIST OF TABLES One Year Holding Period Return Data . . . . Three Year Holding Period Return Data . . . Variables Selected for Each Holding Period- Discriminant Function Listed in Declining Order of Importance . . . . . . . . . . . Variables Common to all Three Data for Each Holding Period . . . . . . . . . . . Spearman Rank Correlation Values (R8) for Each Discriminant Function. . . . . . Page 46 47 50 51 53 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Capital Market Theory Due to the pioneering work of Markowitz1 and to subsequent con- tributions by Sharpe,2 Lintner,3 Mossin,4 Fama,5 and others, modern capital market theory has become a widely accepted explanation of the equilibrium prices of capital assets under conditions of uncertainty. In recent years the investment community has become increasingly aware of the implications of capital market theory for investment practice.6 For example, the widely used Value Line investment service includes beta coefficient data for most stocks listed on the New York Stock 1Markowitz, Harry, "Portfolio Selection," Journal of Finance 2Sharpe, William F., "Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk," Journal of Finance (September 1964), pp. 425-442. 3Lintner, John, "The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgeting," Review of Economics and Statistics (February 1965), pp. 13-17. 4M'ossin, Jan, "Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market," Econometrics (October 1966), pp. 768-783. 5Fama, Eugene F., "Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Some Clarifying Comments," Journal of Finance (March 1968), pp. 29—40. 6For example, refer to many articles in recent years appearing in the Financial Analysts Journal, a publication oriented toward the practicing financial analyst. Exchange. The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) in the Sharpe-Lintner form states three things: (1) that a portfolio or security's covari- ance of rate of return with that of the market is the appropriate measure of risk; (2) that the beta coefficient is a useful measure of this risk; and (3) that expected returns for a portfolio are propor- tional to the degree of risk as measured by the beta coefficient.7 The CAPM assumes that investment decisions are based upon a trade off between the two parameters of risk and return. While the model is obviously a simplification of reality, it nevertheless may provide a useful means for explaining the process which determines security prices. In a test of the CAPM, Sharpe and Cooper have shown that, in general, average annual returns of lowbrisk portfolios tended to have lower average returns than high-risk portfolios.9 The annual returns were generally consistent with the CAPM on average over the entire holding period (1931-1967), but conformance to the theory declined as the time period under study was shortened. The degree to which this 7For a detailed exposition of the capital asset pricing model and the beta coefficient, see: Williath. Sharpe, Portfolio Theory and Capital Market (New York: 'McGrawbHill Book Co., 1970), or see: J. C. Francis, and S. H. Archer, Portfolio Analysis (Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1971). 8For a more detailed summary of the explicit and implicit assump- tions involved in the capital asset pricing model see Jensen, Michael C., "The Foundations and Current State of Capital Market Theory," in Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, M. C. Jensen, ed. (New York Praeger Publishers Inc., 1972), p. 5. 9Sharpe, William.F., and Guy M. Cooper, "Risk-Return Classes of New York Stock Exchange Common Stocks, 1931-1967," Financial Analysts Journal (March 1972). 3 occurred, however, was not specified. The portfolios making up each tested risk-return decile were also quite large, ranging from.47 to 99 securities each. The fact that firms which did not exist at the end of the period (but did exist prior to this time) were not included in the samples constituted a possible source of bias in the return calcu- lations. In a similar study of the Sharpe-Lintner form of the CAPM, Black, Jensen, and Scholes (BJS) found that the model was not completely ade- quate as a description of security returns since there was a tendency for high-beta portfolios to offer lower than expected returns and for lowhbeta portfolios to exhibit higher returns than expected.10 They then proposed and tested an expanded version of the CAPM which expressed the return on a security as a linear function of both the market return and a portfolio whose covariance with the market return was zero. Over the 35-year holding period of the BJS study extending from 1931 through 1965, the relationship between average excess monthly returns and the degree of systematic risk, as measured by the beta coefficient, was approximately linear. The same linear relationship also was found for the four equal nonoverlapping subperiods of 105 months duration. In the BJS study the portfolios tested were large, ranging in size from 58 to 109 securities each. 10Black, Fisher, Michael C. Jensen, and Myron Scholes, "The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests," in Jensen, Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. 4 Studies by both Blume11 and Levy12 have demonstrated that indi— vidual firms changed risk classes infrequently over time. For diversi- fied portfolios, risk class levels were very stable since those secu- rities which moved to higher risk classes tended to be counterbalanced by those moving to lower risk classes. Investors could it was argued, select portfolios from any desired utility-maximizing risk level by simply relying upon the historical beta levels of the component securi- ties as unbiased estimators of the "true" portfolio beta. The weighted average beta of the selected portfolio would thus constitute an implicit forecast of future returns of the portfolio relative to market returns. For example, if the beta level for the selected portfolio were 1.5, then the portfolio's future returns should be 1.5 times the market return. A study by Evans and Archer showed that the degree of unsystematic risk could be almost eliminated through diversification using a small number of issues, thus a large portfolio was deemed to be unnecessary. In fact, a large portfolio required greater administrative effort as the number of securities grew beyond the necessary number (usually less than but seldom more than twenty stocks). After the initial study by Blume and the later Levy study, the usefulness of historical betas as proxies for their (unobservable) future values became a matter of great interest. 11Blume, Marshall E., "On the Assessment of Risk," Journal of Finance (March 1971). 12Levy, Robert A., "On the Short-term Stationarity of Beta Coefficients," Financial Analysts Journal (November 1971). 13Evans, John L., and S. H. Archer, "Diversification and the Reduction of Dispersion: An Empirical Analysis," Journal of Finance (December 1968), pp. 761-769. 5 The practical implication of this reasoning was that the investor might want to select a utility-maximizing level of nondiversifiable or market risk (represented by the weighted average beta coefficient of the port- folio). He could diversify away most unsystematic risk (even a few securities would suffice), and then expect future returns proportional to the level of systematic risk taken.14 The proportional relationship between risk and return was demon- strated by the Sharpe and Cooper,15 and the Black, Jensen, and Scholes16 studies. These studies strongly affirmed the existence of a reward for bearing risk over the long run. While the prOportional relationship between risk and return is reasonably stable over long time periods, little is known regarding this relationship over shorter time periods when small portfolios form the investment vehicle. Knowledge of whether the CAPM is a valid predictor of the returns to be derived from.small portfolios over short holding periods is important for two reasons: First, adequate levels of diversification can be achieved with a small number of securities, and secondly, many investors do in fact invest for short holding periods. Multiple Discriminant Analysis In investment analysis the price of an equity security is fre- quently considered to represent the present value of future dividends.17 14For example, this basic strategy is advocated by Francis, Jack, Investments: Analysis and Management (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1972), p. 590. 5Sharpe and Cooper, op. cit. 16Black, Jensen, and Scholes, op. cit. 17J. B. Williams, The Theory of Investment Value (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1938).‘ 6 When this approach is used, fundamental analysis determines a stock's "intrinsic" value by estimating future dividend streams and then dis- counting these by a rate dependent upon risk. Intrinsic value would next be compared with market price and a decision made as to whether the stock should be bought or sold short. Fundamental analysis assumes the market at times prices securities inefficiently. In such a case opportunities exist for the fundamental analyst to acquire underpriced issues which the market will subsequently reprice. Numerous common stock investment strategies have been practiced both individually and in combination with one another.18 The concept of market inefficiency, however, is perhaps most completely embodied in the "undervalued issue strategy," popular within the ranks of funda- mentally oriented investors and analysts. Douglas Hayes provided a useful description of this strategy:19 "But as a special strategy designed to obtain greater than average returns available on common stocks generally, it has come to be identified with a particular type of company emerging from a behavioral theory of the market. The be- havioral theory is that the market tends to exaggerate the importance of unfavorable developments or perhaps the mere absence of a highly dynamic potential. By the same token it is held that the market also tends to overemphasize favorable factors. In short, the theory is the logical extension of the vogue theory, noted in connection with growth stocks, to an anti-vogue theory. The view is that prices of certain stocks may be unreasonably depressed because of an undue emphasis on the immediate past earnings performance or on some unfavorable information of a general sort. 8For a discussion of other types of investment strategies such as trading, cyclical timing, buy—and-hold, etc., see: Hayes, Douglas A., Investments: Analysis and Management (New York: Macmillan Co., 1966), Second ed., Ch. 5. lgIbido’ Pp. 77-78. 7 Substantial returns may well be obtained, it is argued, when and if it becomes clear that the adverse performance was indeed temporary or that the potential problems were not as catastr0phic as was generally believed. Recognition of the improved situation may take time, but ultimately, it is held, the market price will reflect the improvement. Note that it is not growth that is anticipated, but only a reasonable recovery to former levels of earnings performance. Such a recovery should, it is argued, ultimately produce investment returns well in excess of the secular performance of the mar- ket as a whole. Mbreover, because prices are depressed at the time of acquisition, dividend yields on cost are usually quite satisfactory if further reductions in the dividend rate do not subsequently take place." Hayes further stated that the undervalued issue strategy would take a great deal of skill on the part of the investor and often con- siderable patience while waiting for the market to appropriately value the stock. The undervalued issue could also be quite risky because of the difficulty faced in distinguishing temporary from permanent adver- sity. Support for the strategy of selecting inappropriately priced securities can be found in Graham, Dodd, and Cottle's classic work:20 "It is our thesis that the stocks of companies with dis- appointing showings usually sell lower than they should, for the same basic reason that stocks as a whole sell too low during periods of depression. The significance of the unfavorable conditions is exaggerated. If this view is correct, the "poorer issues will normally be undervalued in the market in relation to the better issues, with the possible exception of low-priced stocks as a whole, which attract a special sort of speculative interest. Broadly speaking, this generalization is valid. Our view is based on the principle that in the majority of cases companies showing an unfavorable trend of earnings will reach a bottom at some time and that thereafter their earnings will fluctuate irregularly around some indicated average or normal base. The market price will usually 20Graham, Benjamin, David L. Dodd, and Signey Cottle, Security Analysis Principles and Techniques (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1962), Fourth Ed., p. 696. 8 have fallen well below the value indicated by the latter as well as by the asset-value factors. Consequently there is an undervaluation and a practical opportunity for profit- able purchase. Quantitative techniques may play an important role in aiding the process of security analysis and selection. Multiple discriminant analysis is one technique which is used in the field of Finance21 which might be useful for security analysis. Edward Altman used multiple discriminant analysis successfully for the prediction of cor- porate bankruptcy. He said the following concerning possible applica- tions of multiple discriminant analysis to investment problems:22 The potentially useful applications of an accurate bank- ruptcy predictive model are not limited to internal consider- ations or to credit evaluation purposes. An efficient pre- dictor of financial difficulties could also be a valuable technique for screening out undesirable investments. 0n the more optimistic side it appears that there are some very real opportunities for benefits. Since the model is basically predictive the analyst can utilize these predictions to recommend appropriate investment policy.... While the above results are derived from an admittedly small sample of very special firms, the potential implications are of interest. If an individual already owns stock in a firm whose future appears dismal, according to the model, he should sell in order to avoid further price declines. The sale would 1For example see such studies as J. E. Walter, "A Discriminant Function for Earnings Price Ratios of Large Industrial Corporations," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. XLI (February 1959), pp. 44- 52; K. V. Smith, Classification of Investment Securities Using MDA, Institute Paper #101 (Purdue University, Institute of Research in the Behavioral, Economic, and Management Sciences, 1965); Edward I. Altman, "Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy," Journal of Finance, vol. XXIII (September 1968), pp. 589-609; W. T. Carlton and E. M. Lerner, "Statistical Credit Scoring of Municipal Bonds," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking I (November, 1969); A. S. McCall and R. A. Eisenbeis, "Some Effects of Affiliations Among Mutual Savings and Commercial Banks," FDIC Working Paper No. 71-1, 1970; R. A. Eisenbeis, "A Study of the Delineation of Geographic Markets for Business Loans," Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin, 1971. 22Altman, p. 608. 9 prevent further loss and provide capital for alternative investments. A different policy could be adopted by those aggressive investors looking for short-sale opportunities. An investor utilizing this strategy would have realized a 26 per cent gain on those listed securities eligible for short-sales in the original sample of bankrupt firms.... Keith Smith, discussing his successful application of multiple discriminant analysis to the classification of securities into specific investment grades stated, "In addition, it should be possible to extend the analysis to other types of investment, i.e., to search for variable profiles which characterize distinct investment Opportunities and thereby enhance the portfolio selection process."23 Research Purpose The purpose of this research was twofold. The first purpose was to test the Sharpe-Lintner capital asset pricing model on the sample of common stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange which had the poorest past price performance during a calendar year° Small portfolios of less than 20 securities taken over relatively short holding periods of l and 3 years were tested to ascertain whether their performance during holding periods subsequent to the year of poor performance yielded returns consistent with those which would have been expected according to the Sharpe-Lintner CAPM, given the market performance during the same holding period. The second purpose of the research was to ascertain whether multiple discriminant analysis (MDA) could predict future relative performance ranks of securities based upon a profile of their financial characteristics. The results provided information rela- tive to the potential usefulness of MDA as a tool for augmenting the 23Smith, pp. 33-34. 10 security analysis process. Outline of Tests This research was limited to those common stocks which experi- enced the greatest percentage price declines during each of the calendar years 1956 through 1968 for the purpose of testing the CAPM, and for the years 1962 through 1971 for the MDA tests. Various subperiods from within these yearly groups were selected for the particular tests which are outlined below. Capital Asset Pricing Model Tests The test of the Sharpe-Lintner capital asset pricing model (CAPM) entailed the comparison of realized one-year and three-year holding period returns (exclusive of cash dividends) with returns conditionally expected by the CAPM given the market return over the same holding periods and the historically calculated beta. The initial sample con- sisted of the twenty common stocks which had experienced the greatest percentage price losses during each of the calendar years 1956 through 1967. Firms without calendar year accounting periods as well as utilities, financial corporations, and transportation companies, were excluded from the original sample. The null hypothesis was that no significant different existed between the expected return (conditional upon the subsequent market return and the historical portfolio beta) and actual returns. The conditional expected portfolio return for time t was E (1) The expected return on a portfolio, E(Rp), is equal to the degree of nondiversifiable risk, Bp, times the expected return of the market, E(RM). R = E 2 E( p) 8p (RM) < > The CAPM asserts that return should be positively related to Bp’ the measure of risk. The model was tested using the relationship E(Rpt) = prMt (2.1) where E 0 were tested at the a - .05 level of significance. The Spearman rank correlation coefficient was selected as the test statistic since performance ranking abaility was felt to be the most meaningful criterion of usefulness for investment purposes. The chief reason for having chosen the nonparametric Spearman rather than the parametric Pearson correlation coefficient was that the former test does not depend upon assumptions about the underlying distribution of the actual and predicted values. It only requires the assumption that they be continuous, and under the null hypothesis, independent. Both assumptions were easily satisfied. This test, when compared to the 43 Pearsonian r under conditions where all conditions of the latter test hold has an asymptotic relative efficiency of .912.15 15A. Stuart, “Asymptotic Relative Efficiency of Tests and the Derivatives of their Power Function,"'Skandinavisk Aktaurietidskrift, parts 3-4, pp. 163-169. CHAPTER IV RESULTS Capital Asset Pricing Model Test Results Table 4.1 below shows the results of the CAPM test for the port— folios held for one-year periods. Table 4.2 shows the results for the three-year holding periods. Column (1) of each table lists the indi- t:_ vidual periods. These periods ran from.January l to January 1 of the I years given. Column (2) lists the number of securities which comprised each individual portfolio. This number differs from the preliminary sample of twenty due to the exclusion of firms with noncalendar year accounting periods and those which were not industrials. Column (3) lists the observed market returns (represented by the S&P 500 Composite Index), RMt’ for each time period t. Column (4) lists the historical average beta, bp, for each port- folio. The portfolio beta is modified by the adjustment factor esti- mated by Sharpe and Cooper1 and given by equation (3) of the previous chapter. At two significant digits the beta and market sensitivity measures for each portfolio were identical in all but one case. Column (6) lists the conditional expected portfolio return, given the historical beta and the market return over the same holding period. 1William F. Sharpe and Guy M. Cooper, "Risk-Return Classes of New York Stock Exchange Common Stocks, 1931-1967," Financial Analysts Journal (March 1972). 44 45 This value was calculated by formula (2.2) of the previous chapter. Column (7) shows the observed portfolio returns over the holding periods, while column (8) shows the differences between actual and expected portfolio returns. As discussed in the previous chapter, returns were defined for this study so as to exclude cash dividends; both actual and expected returns were adjusted for this exclusion. Column 8 of Tables 4.1 and 4.2 show in particular how large the differ— ences between actual and expected returns frequently were. The paired difference test of the CAPM involved calculating the t statistic for the differences between actual and conditional ex- pected returns: Where the D values were as given in column (8) of Tables 4.1 and 4.2, and 'B.-f§' n :41 differences, while u was the sample size. The hypotheses were Dt' Sd was the sample standard deviation of return no :'D'= 0 lenfo tested at the a level of .05. For the l-year holding period returns the test statistic was t . '0415 ' ° = .53225 .2702 / IE5 with a critical value of $2.201 and 11 degrees of freedom. For the 3-year holding period returns 46 coo.l omo. omo. mH.H wH.H Hwo. m momalwomfl hum. mum. omH. oo.H oo.H cod. m momalhcaa qu.l omH.l mOH.I mm. mm. mNH.I h nomalooma omN. mom. CHH. NH.H NH.H «mo. OH comalmomfl coo. NON. omH. oH.H 9H.H nHH. NH momaleoaa meN.l HNo.I NNN. NH.H NH.H NON. w eomfllmomfl «OH.I OMN.I eNH.I mo.H mo.H mHH.I HH mcmHlNomH NmH.I NMH. «Hm. mm.H mm.H NMN. HH Noafllaomfl woo.l NOH.I oeo.l mo.H wo.H mmo.l m HomHloomH moo.l Nno. who. ma. mm. Hwo. m oomdlmmmfi mme. mam. mow. mN.H mN.H mum. 0H manlmmmH neN.l 5mm.l omH.l wH.H mH.H BNH.I NH wmmfllnmma u m u a a. u no u u name 0 Auzm.eo\ummvm3u«muua mm Auzm. o\ mmvm m2. A an Iwuwm weasmwwwm coupon owaomuuom chauum assume aua>au comm ensued mo ooauom oouuooxm was oaaomuuom ouuooexm Iwmoom ouaom moxuoz nooaoz mafia Hmouo< mooauom oo>uomoo Hmoowuwoaoo uoxumz quom mucouommwa Hmouu< 3v AC A3 A3 A13 A3 ANV A3 au moon cuoumm mo powwow oouuooxu odd oaaomuuom oouoomxm Iwuaom ouaom uoxumz noosuz saga Honuu< coosuom oo>uomoo Hmaowugoaoo uoxumz quom oomouowmwn donned Ame Ame Amy any Rev Amv Auv AHV m.¢ mam coaaoo ou unsavooosm Ammv oowuom mswoaom Hoaoouuunm one no euwooq COHmmm UZHQAOS mumm Mom azam «add mummy AA< OH zczzoo mMAM ¢.¢ mum<fi 52 That is, firms in the 1967-1971 test period which were drawn from years in which the general market declined (1969 and 1970) were used to test the nine- and thirty-three-month discriminant functions which had been constructed utilizing only those samples of firms which had been drawn from those years in the sample period in which the market had declined (1962 and 1966). The test statistic was 11 n n n 151 xiyi ’ (151 *1) (151 yi) r- S n n n n 2 2 2 2 ‘¢/;1§1 ‘1 ’ (1§1 x1) n1351 Y1 ‘ (1§1 Y1) where n is the number of firms being ranked, x1 is the actual perfor- mance rank and y1 is the rank predicted by the discriminant function- for any firm i - 1,2, ..., n. The resulting r8 correlation coefficient was compared to the .05 significance level for an upper-tail test. If the r8 value exceeded the critical value, the null hypothesis of "no association" between actual and predicted ranks would be rejected. Alternatively, if r8 did not exceed the critical value, the null hypothesis would not be rejected. Table 4.5 shows the sample r8 values for each discriminant func- tion. When these sample statistic values were compared with the critical values of the test statistic, none were found significant at the five percent level. That is, correlations of the magnitude found could be expected to have occurred randomly more often than 5 times out of 100 if the predicted and actual ranks were uncorrelated. It also can be seen that 11 of the 18 functions have the correct sign. If no relationship whatsoever existed, one would have expected roughly 53 3. S. no. SSTSSV poems in 3 2382:. as 58a mm 8.- .3. S. “SEAS: spams 3. 3 ”.8339. em 5:8 a Ho.l on. om. Anomalmomav possum uoxuoa munch ou unmovomonm mm ounce mm No. on.: OH. Aoomfl .momav mooNHooo assume mums» ou uaosvomoam mm :uooa mm ee.| 00.: oa.| Anomalmoaav woman» uoxuma oomph cu unsavomoom mm ounce m 0N.|. on. 00. Aooma .Nomav oocuaooo uoxuma pump» on unwovomoom mm ounce m ooauom amok uoooaom usooaom Aoummapomuom soon we use» occupancy ou unoavomoom Humatnoaa vacuum umuam Ammv oowuom wsfiofiom uoaaofiuumm new no suwcoq m ZOHHUZDK Hz HZMHUHhmmoo ZOHH¢AMMMOU MZ