JIHIHJHI I \ 5 WIHHIWHHHUIHIIWINIWIWWW! 557 THS I'HES" lllllllllllllllllllllllllllllzllllllzll mm 312 Michigan Stan University This is to certify that the thesis entitled THE ROLE OF WORKERS' SELF-MANAGEMENT IN SOCIALIST DEVELOPMENT: AN EXAMINATION OF WORKERS' COUNCILS IN POLAND AND YUGOSLAVIA . presented by i Ginger E. Macheski has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for , Jasm— degree in MEL. 4%»; W «22%; 7 .7 Major professor Date 5//c/ 7? 0-7639 OVERDUE FINES ARE 25¢ PER DAY PER ITEM Return to book drop to remove this checkout from your record. THE ROLE OF WORKERS' SELF-MANAGEMENT IN SOCIALIST DEVELOPMENT: AN EXAMINATION OF WORKERS' COUNCILS IN POLAND AND YUGLOSLAVIA BY Ginger E. Macheski A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS Department of Sociology ABSTRACT THE ROLE OF WORKERS' SELF-MANAGEMENT IN SOCIALIST DEVELOPMENT: AN EXAMINATION OF WORKERS' COUNCILS IN POLAND AND YUGOSLAVIA BY Ginger E. Macheski This paper examines both theoretically and empirically, the role of workers' self-management in socialist develop- ment. Marx's concepts of alienation and human nature are used to develop a framework to examine data provided by existing studies of workers' councils in Poland and Yugoslavia. The major findings of this study are while the legis- lative role of workers' councils in both countries appear to promote socialist goals, this premise is not upheld in the actual functioning of the councils. The viability of Polish workers' councils has been successfully mitigated, and Yugoslav councils are controlled by management. This paper concludes that in order for actual control by the producers to be realized, future forms of self- management must not solely attempt to integrate workers into existing managerial forms of organizational control, but must challenge and restructure the underlying production process. Implications for further research are explored. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page LIST OF TABLES ii I. INTRODUCTION 1 II. THEORETICAL GOALS OF SOCIALIST WORKERS' COUNCILS 2 III. THE HISTORY OF POLISH AND YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCILS 16 IV. THE FUNCTIONING OF POLISH AND YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCILS 20 V. DISCUSSION 26 VI. CONCLUSION 29 NOTES 31 LIST OF REFERENCES 37 Table Table Table Table LIST OF TABLES PERCEIVED INFLUENCE INFLUENCE WITHIN WORKERS' COUNCILS PARTICIPATION AND SUGGESTIONS AT YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCIL MEETINGS CHARACTERISTICS OF YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCIL MEMBERS ii Page 23 23 25 25 I . INTRODUCTION There is a substantial body of Marxist literature1 which identifies workers' self-management as a potential vehicle under socialism for challenging the dehabilitating social relations that have been established by capitalism. Predicted benefits of workers' self-management range from "the wither- ing away of the state"2 and the end of alienation3 to the more modest claim of providing channels of worker input into the production process. In addition to these theoretically oriented treatises, there exists a number of studies which by survey or observation discuss the structure and functioning of existing forms of socialist self-management. A majority of these studies depict workers' councils as a model of socialist participation. Very few attempts have been made to integrate the two bodies of literature.4 The theoretical predictions are sparsely grounded in concrete conditions and the studies of participation are largely unconnected to any theoretical orientation. As a result, the theoretical assertions remain speculative and the empirical studies provide little insight into the impact of these structures. A number of questions can be raised by looking closely at workers' councils. In particular, do workers' councils provide an alternative to capitalist relations of production? What new avenues of input or access to control do workers' councils provide? Is there some basis for the theoretical predictions? In other words, what changes do workers' councils bring about in the structure of work? In workers' control 1 2 over their own lives? And what implications do these changes have for the theoretical postulates? These questions deline- ate the concerns of this paper. By clarifying the theoretical basis of socialist self- management and then using the resulting framework to examine the structure and functioning of workers' councils in two socialist countries, an attempt will be made to gain insight into the role of workers' councils in the process of social— ist transformation. The focus of analysis is Poland and Yugoslavia. The well-publicized Yugoslav system of workers' self-management and the less familiar Polish experience with workers' coun- cils will be examined. These two socialist countries‘have some basic similarities that facilitate analysis, yet retain sufficient differences to provide comparisons.5 II. THEORETICAL GOALS OF SOCIALIST WORKERS' SELF-MANAGEMENT Before we can begin to examine the role of workers' councils in the socialist development of Poland and Yugoslavia, the term "socialist development" must be clarified. What are the criteria for socialist development? What are the goals and the tasks for this process? Attempts to answer these queries have produced many different responses with a wide range of basic premises. These premises range from how the communists achieved power, i.e., was there a workers' revolution,6 to what form of government is present, i.e., centralized vs. decentralized.7 These criteria each have some useful points to offer, but as 3 a whole, provide little insight to the problem of developing a framework from which to judge the impact or importance of new forms of social organization. A more useful approach is outlined by Braverman.8 Instead of delineating sets of criteria with which to judge the validity of a particular country's claim to socialism, Braverman maintains that so- cialism should be considered as a process which begins at the inception of communist rise to power and evolves into new structures and forms of social organization.9 By utili- zing the idea of socialism as a process, as a proposed tran- sition from capitalist forms of organization toward the de- velopment of socialist forms of organization, or the develop- ment of social institutions which promote communist goals, the problem of defining socialism can be translated into theoretically delineating the processes involved and examining the related structures and processes within each country that is attempting the transformation. Under this approach, iden- tifying which countries are "socialist" becomes relatively unimportant. Any country which proclaims itself as socialist can thus be considered. The important focus becomes that of identifying which processes within each country are developing toward the goals of socialism, and which processes are contra- dicting these goals.10 To begin the examination of the processes involved in the development of socialism, we must have some understanding of what is meant by socialist goals. This is a task that can not be fully delineated here. However, certain themes in Marx's writings can be identified which provide a sufficient 4 framework for the purposes at hand. The theme of human development can be found throughout the works of Marx. To him, a person's development of his/ her potential is structured by the predominant social re- lations which are created by the existing organization of production. Under capitalism, Marx documents conditions which restrict or even negate the possibility of anything but segmented and stunted personal development.11 Thus, socialism represents an attempt to change these limiting structures, to create a system under which individual poten- tials can be more fully realized. Few attempts have been made to elaborate the goals of socialism beyond this basic human development orientation. The most recent discussions of socialism focus on "is this country still socialist" debates,12 i.e., is the U.S.S.R. actually state-capitalism? Out of these debates, Gordon,13 in his article "Capitalist Efficiency and Socialist Efficiencyfl has crystalized two underlying basic orientations toward socialist transition: ". . . two main logical conceptions have dominated traditional Marxian views of socialist transition . . . Each of those conceptions corresponds to a different . l4 ViSion of the ultimate communist objective." In other words, throughout Marxian literature, two pictures of future communist society have been developed. Assumptions about socialist goals are implicitly contained within these orientations.15 The simplest of these two views is the 'free labor' concept. This version of communism is that of a society free 5 from want and much of the drudgery of labor. This type of communist society would be identified by a minimum of socially necessary labor time equally divided among all members of society. This means that the total amount of work needed to produce a high standard of living for all the members of the society would be negligible. This work would be equally shared by all those in the society. To reach this goal, the task of socialism would be to develop the productive forces16 in order to reduce the labor time necessary to fulfill the needs of society and to develop mechanisms which would ensure the equal distribution of both socially necessary labor time and newly liberated free time. Insignificant socially necessary labor time is also an important feature of the second orientation, the 'collective labor' view of communism. As in the free labor view, this labor would be distributed equally among all members of the society. But in addition to these characteristics, dramatic changes would be seen in the social relations of society. The organization of society would promote shared collective or co-operative relationships through which everyone is equally free and responsible. This focus on social relations complicates the task of social transformation. Not only must the productive forces of society be developed and expanded, but two additional tasks must be undertaken in the socialist transformation to achieve the communism pictured in the collective labor conception. The relations of production must continually be developed in a manner that increases 6 avenues for workers' participation in collective and re- sponsible social relations. Secondly, mechanisms must be created to ensure that both the work to be done and the new co-operative relations are equally distributed among all members of the society. Support, in the form of selected quotations, for both these conceptions can be found in the works of Marx, Mao, and Lenin. Rather than engage in a futile attempt to dis— cern what these monumental thinkers really meant, it is per- haps more useful to subject each perspective to a test in the context of the focus of this paper.17 What tools does each view give us to understand the development of contem- porary socialism; to evaluate the experience of existing socialist countries? By these criteria, the fundamental differences between the two conceptions become clear. Both conceptions stress the need for continually developing and expanding the pro- ductive forces of the society during socialist transition.18 However, the free labor view of communism focuses almost exclusively on peoples' fight to master nature, or the struggle to develop means to provide all peOple with the material requisites of life. Through this focus,the inter- dependent character of relations between people is ignored. The social relations of production are of concern only to the extent necessary to determine the distribution of the work load. Without an emphasis on the social character of pro- duction, this view gives us no framework from which to under- stand the human dynamics of the system; how the people of 7 the society are to be involved in the process, both in terms of developing their potentials and in terms of their political power. A logical, albeit extreme extension of the free labor view would be a technological or economic deterministic approach to the tasks of the socialist tran- sition. One would look for increases in the productive capacities and the standard of living in a country, along with trends toward a more equitable distribution of wealth as indicators of advances in socialist development.19 Development of technology, not people, would be the path to communism. In contrast, within the collective labor View, the social character of production is central. Therefore, from this perspective, a society would be seen as moving along the path to communism if, in addition to developing the forces of production, the relations of production were organized in such a way as to both maximize the ability of the working class to increase its control over the means of production and the society as a whole and to promote the development of human potential. This emphasis provides an important starting point in the examination of the social dynamics of existing socialist countries. Changes in the relations of production, as well as in the amount of work, become important elements to examine. Thus, an understand- ing of the role of workers' self-management is crucial in evaluating existing socialist countries within this view. However, this orientation, as presented, lacks develop- ment. Before we can critically analyze the functioning of 8 existing forms of workers' self-management, two aspects must be clarified. How would this focus on social relations be developed? And what changes would be made in a society's structure to facilitate this aim? To answer these questions, a twofold process must be undertaken; first, we must have an understanding of what is meant by human development, and secondly, an understanding of the structural constraints which hinder this development under capitalism. By looking at Marx's concept of alienation we can begin to gain insight into these issues. Marx dis- cusses the negative effects capitalist organization has on human development through prevalent social relations by elaborating a theory of alienation. Alienation can be exa— mined both in terms of Marx's formulation of human nature20 and the interrelation of social organization and human de- velopment potentials. For Marx, as with his other concepts and indeed his entire analysis, human nature is not a final and unchanging phenomenon. Instead, human nature is a dynamic social pro- cess within which certain potentialities or capabilities of people are either given expression or are thwarted. As Israel explains, for Marx: "Man is the totality of social relations seen in a historical perspective. His social re- lations are changed through the development of the productive forces, which alter the existing structure of a society1 which in turn changes his SOCial relations. This unique interactive definition stems from two central assumptions Marx makes about the nature of people: 1) people are active social beings, and 2) people relate to nature through their activities. First among all things for Marx is the belief that people are social beings. A person lives in relation to other people and is a product of this interaction. In this way, Marx's definition of human nature is a sociological definition, he views humankind not as individuals but ra- ther in the context of all people.22 Thus, an understanding of the nature of people can not be separated from the so- 23 An important part of this social setting is cial setting. the labor process. The distinctive characteristic of hu- man work for Marx is that this labor is conscious and pur- poseful.24 It is through the interaction of their labor and the social environment that people are able to create products to satisfy their needs. Human labor is a con- scious and active process. "By this acting on the external world and changing it, he at the same time changes his own nature." For Marx, people are active, creative beings. Through a unified labor process, a person creates mechanisms to satis- fy his/her needs and in turn his/her potentials are developed. But it is precisely within these processes that the phenomenon of alienation arises. For example, the unity of conception and execution in labor is an essential component in the creative development of people. However, this unity is not inviolable. It is possible within the labor process for a division to occur; for one person to conceive of a project while another executes the task. The social relations which develop from this and other separations are both the lO process and results of alienation. For Marx, capitalism epitomizes this process of segmen- tation and separation. Under capitalism, all traits by which Marx distinguished humans from other organisms have been severed. Thus, alienation is the disruption of the ba- sic relations of people; a person's relation to his/her activity, the product of that activity, other people, and human species being.26 This disruption must be analyzed in the context of the social structure under which it occurs, capitalism. This point raises questions about the source of aliena- tion. As Novack has suggested: "The alienation of the worker and his labor means that something has basically changed in the life of the worker. What is it? Normally, everyone has some creative capa- bilities, certain talents lodged in him, untapped potentialities for human develop- ment which should be expressed in his labor activity. However, once the institution of wage-labor is prevglent, these possibilities become nullified." In other words, a starting point for understanding the sources of alienation lies in the wage labor-system. Let us focus on what is meant by wage-labor, and by what processes this institution has evolved. Labor under capitalism is wage-labor, a contractual agreement under which one person sells his/her labor power, his/her ability to do work, to another. The essential fac- tor in this process is the transfer of control. A person no longer may claim responsibility for his/her labor or the product of that labor, they are now controlled by the capita- list. Marx discusses three conditions within the productive ll forces of capitalist society which create and in turn are strengthened by this fundamental change in the labor pro- cess. They are: l) the development of private ownership of the means of production, i.e., private property under capitalism, 2) the evolution of the division of labor, and 3) the relationships created by the reduction of labor to a commodity. These three characteristics are not totally separate facets of capitalist production systems, but are interrelated phenomena within the overall market structure of capitalism. In combination, these characteristics result in the subordination of labor to capital.28 The relationship of the capitalist private property system of ownership to alienation is probably the clearest to discern. Under capitalism, the means of production, the tools and technology needed to produce, are owned by indivi- duals. This separation of the means of subsistence from those who produce creates the basis for wage-labor. Now those who do not own must enter into an agreement with those who own the means of production in order to survive. PeOple must sell their labor power for a wage. As the institution of private property becomes widespread, it leads to both the process of alienation (people are separated from the mecha- nisms of productions and must enter into a wage-labor contract) and a product of alienation (the objects people create do not belong to them, but are added to the capitalists' store- house). The second condition through which labor is alienated under capitalism, division of labor, is closely related to 12 the concept of private property. While the institution of private ownership of the means of production underlines the social relationship between the individual and the tools and products of production, the division of labor emphasizes the connections between the individual and the organization of the production process. An important distinction must be made when discussing the division of labor. In all societies, there exists some division of the tasks necessary to the maintenance of that society. Each individual alone could not possibly provide him/herself with more than the bare means of subsistence. It is only through this social division of labor, the break- down of tasks into occupations or branches or production, that society as a whole is able to develop and progress. On the other hand, the manufacturing division of labor, which exists within the capitalist labor process,29 is the divi- sion of the processes involved in making a product into many separate tasks done by different workers. This breakdown denies the worker any connection with the finished product of his/her activity. The worker acquires only the knowledge required to perform one small part of the product's manufac- ture. S/he is no longer aware of the entire process, the product does not appear as a direct result of his/her work, severing the essential creative unity between conception and execution. In this divided production, the individual is given a limited role, and only a fraction of his/her know- ledge and capabilities are brought to use. People are aliena- ted from their potentialities and from the possibility of 13 full human development. It is through the expansion of capitalist private pro- perty and the increased segmentation of the production process within the manufacturing division of labor that la- bor becomes a commodity. A commodity is a product which is related to other products through an exchange value. With- in capitalism, this exchange value is not based upon intrin- sic human needs nor societal use, but merely upon equivalent exchanges of these products' most common denominator: money. In the capitalist market, ten dollars of gold and ten dollars of grain are of equal value, no matter how many people are hungry. Ten dollars of labor power may be exchanged for ten dollars of equivalent worth in any product, no more or no less. This places the mechanism of human survival, labor, squarely within the vagarities of the market. If the supply of labor power is large, wages are reduced. If technological advances increase productivity, labor power loses exchange value. Labor as a commodity is something to be disposed of, to be bought and sold. Accordingly, workers begin to View their labor power as an object, a thing they own which must be bartered for survival. People must compete with other people for the beneficial sale of their work capability. People become things to other people. The social base of this pro- cess becomes masked by the appearance of these commodity relations between things. In summary, in the Marxian perspective, alienation is the result of specific historical conditions organized in a l4 definite mode of production. It is these facets of social organization which limit the development of collective so- cial relations, and therefore, are the focus of change under the collective labor model of socialist transformation. The planners of socialist countries must consciously develop mechanisms which contradict these processes and develop new bases for collective social relations. Within socialist countries, insofar as the institution of capitalist private property has been abolished, and inso- far as the means of production are collectively owned by the people through the state, this condition of alienation has been reduced. Profit no longer falls into the hands of private individuals but belongs to the society as a whole. In both Poland and Yugoslavia, only a small portion of in- dustry remains in private hands.30 Therefore, this struc- tural component of alienation has little importance in our study of socialist development. However, developed forms of both division of labor and commodity relations are still very much present in the struc- ture of most socialist countries. Under capitalism, mental work is divided from manual work, responsibility and autho- rity are hierarchically distributed, and the production process is segmentalized into minute and meaningless tasks. All these mechanisms serve to take responsibility for and control of the labor process away from the worker. These limiting structures are also found in the industrial concerns of Poland and Yugoslavia. Although the economies of socialist countries have been 15 dramatically restructured, labor as a commodity relations prevail. Workers must still sell their labor power under market-like conditions. A worker's well-being depends upon selling his/her labor power. Competition between workers for material rewards abounds, and in many instances, is en- couraged by incentive programs.31 The presence of these restrictive structures within a socialist country in no way negates the feasibility of the socialist goal of new forms of social relations. Only a simplistic application of the Marxian theory of historical development would imply that the mere abolition of private property systems of capitalism would totally negate the existence of capitalistic social and economic relations. Rather, as Braverman points out in his introduction to Labor and Monopoly Capital, Marx's analysis of historical develop- ment indicates: ". . .that the same productive forces that are characteristic of the close of one epoch are also characteristic of the opening of the suc- ceeding epoch; indeed how could it be other- wise, since political and social revolutions, . . ., do not on the morrow provide a society with a brand new technology."32 Therefore, when attempting to gain an understanding of socialist countries, the problem is not one of merely documenting how far short these countries fall of their communist ideal or how closely they resemble capitalism. Rather, the challenge lies in attempting to identify, given the continued existence of forms of capitalist social and economic relations, the trends and processes within these countries which represent changes in these limiting structures. 16 The direction of our examination of workers' councils is now clear. Workers' councils, in order to play a part in the building of collective social relations, must function in such a way as to challenge the position of labor as a commodity, and begin to restructure the manufacturing di- vision of labor within the work process. III. THE HISTORY OF POLISH AND YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCILS To what extent do the workers' councils in Yugoslavia and Poland aid in the accomplishment of these aims? A brief examination of the history of workers' councils in each of these countries is a useful point of departure in answering this question. As previously noted, tensions between Yugoslavia and the Soviet Union culminated in a breach of all relations between the two countries in 1948. Up until this time, Yugoslav economic development closely followed the Soviet model. Workers' participation was limited to membership on committees called workers' representative councils. The function of these committees was largely advisory.33 Cut off by the breach from all former trade partners, technical advisors, and external sources of investment, the centralized economy of Yugoslavia faltered. Major economic reforms oriented toward decentralizing economic control were intro- duced in 1950. An important facet of this decentralization process was the LAW OF WORKERS' SELF-MANAGEMENT OF 26 JUNE, 1950. Through this legislation, the rights of management were given to workers' councils. In general, workers' councils 17 exercise these rights by: l) Approving the basic plans and final accounting of the enterprise; 2) Making decisions for the management of the enterprise and fulfillment of the economic plan; 3) Electing the management committee; 4) Making enterprise regulations, subject to the approval of the management committee of the regional association of the enter- prise; 5) Evaluating the work of management; 6) Distributing that part of the enterprise's profit which remains after taxes.34 This 1950 law constitutes the formal basis for self-manage- ment. Subsequent legislationhas further strengthened and clarified the position of workers' councils. In 1957, re- visions were made which gave workers' councils more control over the distribution of income within the enterprise. Wages fixed by the state were abolished and each enterprise was left free to develop its own basis for the distribution of net income after taxes between capital, wages, and welfare allocations.35 From 1965 on, legislation has emphasized the concept of enterprises as free associations of work part- ners and has strengthened the independent responsibility of the enterprises. The system of workers' self-management through workers' councils is entrenched in the Yugoslav economy,36 having been established and promoted by those in power.37 The origin and subsequent development of workers' coun- cils in the Polish People's Republic provides a vivid con- trast. In comparison to the Yugoslav system, Polish workers' l8 councils are the product of a far more spontaneous process. During the twenty year span of the Polish Republic, la- 38 After World War II, union leaders bor unions flourished. resumed their activities in socialist Poland. Their inde- pendence was not challenged until the forced merger of the Polish Socialist Party with the Polish Communist Party (PRR) in 1949. The PRR consolidated its control with the LABOR DISCIPLINE LAW OF 1950.39 Unions were no longer autonomous organizations. Instead, their newly legislated function was to support the government policies by mobilizing the work force to meet production quotas and discipline the labor force. Management authority was highly centralized and state appointed. Wages were tied to the meeting of production quotas, and strikes were outlawed. Labor unions became a social branch of management. A Six Year Plan for economic development was instituted. The percentage of national in- come used for reinvestment was increased,40 and as a result, consumption levels failed to keep pace with the increased production. Public discontent with these developments cul- minated in 1955 at the end of the Six Year Plan, when worker unrest resulted in numerous strikes and acts of sabotage.4l Technical workers campaigned against the inefficiency and waste of the system and demanded more autonomy. These acts of resistance paved the way for the return to power of Gomulka and promises of liberalization. Some of the more restrictive labor laws were repealed. Workers' councils, many of which had been formed by the striking workers, were institutionalized. The WORKERS' COUNCIL LAW OF NOVEMBER: 19 1956 allowed for the establishment of workers' councils in manufacturing, agricultural, and construction industries, provided that the majority of workers voted for them. Si- milar to the Yugoslav system, the councils' authority ex- tended to the following functions: 1) Determining the organization and regulation of the enterprise; 2) Advising on improvements in production; 3) Determining production norms, wage schedules, and within set limits, the distribution of end of year bonuses; 4) Expressing opinions on the activity of the enterprise and approving the final balance sheet. The popularity of these councils was immense, and by 1958, all major production units had established them.43 However, the period in which the councils functioned effec- tively was very brief.44 The conflicts inherent between party appointed directors, state-mandated plans, and workers' management became manifest.45 The PRR reacted to these ten- sions by introducing a new form of self-management, a Conference of Workers Self-Government.46 These Conferences were composed of members of existing workers' councils, the union shop committee, and the party committee.47 The execu- tive committee of the worker's councils was enlarged to in- clude the director of the plant, the chairperson of the union committee, and a party representative. The function of workers' participation was changed from managerial to advisory. Under this system, the workers' councils were charged with the execution of the Conference decisions. The 20 parallels to the earlier subordination of labor unions are clear. By 1960, Polish Workers' Councils were dominated by the state apparatus. However, the permanence of this sub- ordination should not be overestimated. Strikes and demon- strations by workers continually challenge these restric- tions.48 Several tenative observations can be drawn about the impact of workers' councils on socialist development from the preceding historical background material. While little insight can be gained about changes in the manufacturing di- vision of labor from these legislative accounts, the struc- tural changes in the position of labor should be noted. Under both systems, workers were given control over wage issues, both in establishing wage schedules and distributing portions of the enterprise's profits. Although workers must still enter into labor contracts, the exchange conditions of this contract may now be set by the workers. The empha- sis in the Yugoslav laws of 1965 upon the free association of partners within an enterprise highlights the potential for co-operative social relations inherent in this change. The provisflmuswhich give workers' council the responsibility for determining the rules and regulations of the enterprise further return control over labor power to the worker, with- in a collective framework. IV. THE FUNCTIONING OF POLISH AND YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCILS However, the enactment of these potentials into legis- lation does not guarantee their successful application. 21 Rather, the actual functioning of workers' councils in both Poland and Yugoslavia must be examined in order to determine to what extent these dimensions are manifest in reality. Although there are many studies which examine the functioning of workers' councils in Yugoslavia, little information is available about the Polish system.49 Most of the studies accessible to Western scholars document the political history of the Polish councils. The remaining few which examine the actual workings of the councils are based on field observations, and are primarily descriptive presentations of personalities, work settings, and reports of meetings. As a result, the following discussion will primarily focus on data obtained from the Yugoslav system, supplemented with excerpts from accounts of the Polish councils. The legislation structuring workers' councils in both Poland and Yugoslavia gives the councils authority to deter- mine regulations and wage schedules and to approve financial plans and balance sheets. Consequently, in terms of legal authority, workers' councils are the major decision making bodies of the production enterprises. But, do workers in practice actually exercise their power? To what extent is workers' council's dominance reflected in enterprise affairs? These questions can be answered by examining the influ- ence structure within enterprises. If workers' councils do indeed fully exercise their legislated power, we would expect councils to be perceived as more influential than management. 22 However, this proposition is not supported by the data.50 In study after study, Yugoslav workers perceive the enter- prise's top management personnel as wielding the most in- fluence. In addition, the professional staff and middle management are also seen to possess more influence than the plant workers' council (see Table 1). Observations in a Polish factory report a similar situation. When asked about the strength of the workers' council in his factory, an ex-union member observed: "We saw that during the workers' council's presidium meetings, management sought to use the new organizations in the same way in which it had been using labor unions, i.e.,"gi com- municate With and to control workers. Further documentation of management's controlling posi- tion can be found in a study in which workers' council members were asked about the distribution of influence with- in the council itself. Management was perceived as having the most influence within workers' councils, and semi- skilled and unskilled workers were thought to have the least influence. Table 2 lists the rank order derived from this study. However, the weight of these observations should not be accepted merely at face value. Workers' councils in both Poland and Yugoslavia were given the power to censure management proposals and decisions.52 Does this perceived difference of the top management reflect tacit approval of their programs by the councils? Is the director carrying out schemes or programs promoted by the workers? Or is management calling the shots? 23 Table 1.* PERCEIVED INFLUENCE Group ' Average Rank Order Top Management 1 Professional Staff 2 Middle Management 3 Workers's Councils 4.5 Board of Management# 4.5 Supervisors 6 The Party 7 Highly Skilled and Skilled Workers 8 Semi and Unskilled Workers 9 *This table was compiled from findings reported by V. Rus, "Influence Structure in Yugoslav Enterprises," Industrial Relations, Vol. 9, No. 2, 1970 and "Workers' Participation in Management in Yugoslavia," International Institute for Labor Studies Bulletin, No. 9, 1972, p. 129-172. #The Board of Management consists of the director, and officials of the Workers' Council, trade union, and Party cell. Table 2.* INFLUENCE WITHIN WORKERS' COUNCILS Group Rank Order Top Management Professional Staff Middle Management Supervisors Highly Skilled and Skilled Workers Semi and Unskilled Workers O‘U'IiD-LONH *Source: V. Bus, 92, cit. 24 Observational studies of Yugoslav workers' council meetings provide some answers to these questions. As seen in Table 3, the first proposition is supported. Not only do management personnel participate twice as much as non- management personnel in the meetings, but accepted propo- sals or suggestions were three times more likely to have been advanced by management personnel. Meeting control by management was also observed by Kolaja in his study of a Polish factory: "We have observed in, that as soon as the plant director entered the scene, he began to dominate it with his verbal pronouncements, while members of the weaving department work- ers' council kept silent. The same obser- vation can be made concerning the meetings of the other two large bodies."53 The stratified nature of this participation is further illuminated by looking at the composition of the workers' councils. There is a disproportionate representation of both managerial, personnel, and white collar workers on the Yugoslav councils. Unskilled workers are sparsely represented within council ranks, yet this group composes over a quarter of the total work force (see Table 4). This trend is accentuated in the composition of the Managing Boards.54 There also appears to be a managerial/worker division based upon topic of discussion. Workers in both Poland and Yugoslavia were more likely to take part in discussions when issues of the distribution of wages, bonuses, or benefits, 55 i.e., housing or vacations, were raised. Although it must be noted, management participation did not drop off in these 25 * Table 3. PARTICIPATION AND ACCEPTED SUGGESTIONS AT YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCIL MEETINGS (in percentages) . l 3 li KOLAJA (1959) L OBRADOVIC (1966) yManagement Non-managerialVManagement Non-managerial' jPersonnel Personnel jPersonnel Personnel ? ,1 ii 3 Participation i 66 34 W 65 35 i . 1 _Accepted ;l t lSuggestions ' 73 27 81 19 I g l. 1 ' *This table was compiled from data presented by J. Obradovic, "Participation and Work Attitudes in Yugoslavia," Industrial Relations, Vol. 9, No. 2, 1970, and the previously cited Kolaja Study. Table 4.* CHARACTERISTICS OF YUGOSLAV WORKERS' COUNCIL MEMBERS# (in percentages) KOLAJA VUSKOVIC % of all employed Ratio (1959) (1965) (1965) Managerial and White Collar: 29 23 15 1-5 . Highly Skilled Workers ; 17 20 ll 1.8 l Semi and Skilled Workers 5 54 49 45 1.01 Unskilled Workers ' O 8 29 .27 y 100 100 100 .— l *This table was compiled from findings presented in the following two studies: Kolaja, Workers' Councils: The Yugoslav Experience, p. 17, and Vuskovic, "Social Inequality in Yugoslavia," p. 40, a paper presented to the Conference of the Croatian Communist Alliance, January 1973. #It should be noted that due to different classification schemes, the two years of data are only roughly comparable. 26 instances. V. DISCUSSION As seen in the above data, the actual functioning of workers' councils does not appear to utilize the authority legislated to the councils. Rather, the councils are domi- nated by managerial and white collar personnel. From these data, we may conclude that in reality, workers' councils do not provide mechanisms for workers to collectively con- trol their labor or represent their interests. Instead, the self-management systems of Poland and Yugoslavia, while pro— viding formalized channels of worker input, were transformed into mechanismsthrough which staff and managerial policies are transmitted. Some tentative conclusions can be made in regard to the role of these existing forms of workers' councils in social- ist development. The trend indicated a continued domination of the labor process by those in managerial and professional occupations. Thus, workers' councils return little control to the immediate producers. This trend strengthens the separation of conception and execution within the labor pro- cesses. It is interesting to note that in no reports were issues relating to the manufacturing division of labor noted. Issues involving the work process, when they were mentioned at all in the recordings of workers' council meetings, were limited to discussions of hours, production efficiency or waste, and machine safety. In light of the stratified compo- sition and participation within workers' councils, one would 27 expect this absence to continue. Changes in the organization of work would directly challenge those occupations which now dominate the direction of the workers' councils. While the position of labor as a commodity is lessened in the legislative form of the self-managment systems, there is little evidence to suggest this is paralleled in the day— to-day functioning of the councils. These observations raise the question of whether the shortcomings of the self-management systems are a matter of education, i.e., do workers have the skills to effective— ly utilize workers' councils, or form, i.e., is there some- thing about the structure of workers' councils which negates the possibility of effective utilization? This question can not be definitely answered here. There are limitations inherent within this examination of the actual functioning of the Yugoslav and Polish workers's councils. The data available do not necessarily cover all areas pertinent to the theorectical concerns, nor are they of sufficient depth to provide some important connections. To fully gauge the impact of workers' councils on both the manufacturing division of labor and labor as a commodity relations, more information and study is warranted. An important facet in mitigating labor as a commodity relations is workers' control over the conditions of their employment. We saw that workers' councils in both countries had the authority, within limits, to set wage schedules. To ascertain the reality of this proposition, we need studies which focus on how this authority is utilized, both in terms 28 of the process involved and the resulting distribution of wages. The decentralized character of Yugoslav enterprises pinpoints another important element in regard to labor as a commodity relations. If workers in one firm act to maxi- mize their own profit, what consequences does this have for other workers and for the society as a whole? The continual presence of inflation and unemployment in the Yugoslav economy underscores the importance of further study of this question. As mentioned previously, little attention has been given in studies of workers' councils to issues of work organization. Therefore, changes in the manufacturing di- vision of labor are difficult to discern. We need more detailed information on both the organization of production in these countries and an expanded account of issues re- lated to production that are raised in workers' council meetings. However, although Poland and Yugoslavia have dra- matic differences in their economic organization, the struc- ture and roles of both countries' workers' councils are remarkably similar. This similarity suggests the need to look at technology. The issue of technology must be addressed both theoretically, i.e., the relationship of technology to capitalism and to work organization, and empirically, i.e., where does the technology in each of these countries come from. If the technology used in Yugoslavia comes from capi- talist nations and Poland's technology from the bureaucratically 29 organized Soviet Union, we would expect the relations of production in Poland and Yugoslavia to mirror the organiza- tion in each of the respective countries. This possibility further underscores the need to examine the organization of work in Poland and Yugoslavia. However, while these limitations represent important considerations, some general observations about Polish and Yugoslav workers' councils' role in socialist development can be made. The goals of socialism imply not only changes in power relations, but also changes in social relations. The existing workers' councils in Poland and Yugoslavia appear to be attempts to involve workers in the management process without attention to the underlying process. No attempt has been made within these existing structures to create new organizations of the productive process which might negate the dehabilitating effects of the manufacturing division of labor. The knowledge and skills of the labor process remain divided. Without this important component, few changes in other social relations can be predicted. VI. CONCLUSION In summary, the findings of the paper are as follows. The viability of Polish workers' councils has been success- fully mitigated. The control of Yugoslav workers' councils is held by the managers. Prospects for the development of collective, co-operative social relations through these or- ganizations are dim. In light of these experiences, it would seem that in order for workers' councils to promote actual 30 control by the producers, future forms of self-management must not solely attempt to integrate workers into existing managerial forms of organizational control, but must chal- lenge and restructure the underlying production process. More work, along the lines previously mentioned, must be done both in the area of theoretical analysis and in the area of concrete examination of existing forms of social organization, before the potential role of worker self- management can be fully understood. NOTES Representative of this body of literature are: Mandel and Novack, The Marxist Theory of Alienation, New York: Pathfinder Press, 1976, and P. Vranicki's essay, "On Alienation," in E. Fromm, Socialist Humanism, Garden City, New York: Double Day Press, 1965. This theme is elaborated in Workers Manage Factories in Yugoslavia, by Marshall Tito, Beograde, 1950. "Overcoming alienation ... begins with the emancipation of the working class, the struggle for the dictatorship of the proletariat, and ends with the realization of social self-management in its most complete form." Mandel and Novak, 1976, p. 34. Attempts to integrate the theory and the praxis of workers' councils are largely limited to the development of economic models. The work of Benjamin Ward and Wlodimierz Brus provide good examples of this type of study. Also see H. Watchel, Workers' Management and Workers' Wages in Yugoslavia; the Theory and Practice of Participatory Socialism, Ithaca, 1973. Prior to the inception of socialism, both Yugloslavia and Poland had largely agriculturally based economies. Poland had pockets of industrial development in the North, while Yugoslavia's industrial development was limited to the large cities and seaport regions. Al- though both countries' experience with socialism began at the end of World War II as members of the Soviet bloc, there were differences in each country's communists' ascension to power. Polish communists were installed by the Red Army, while Yugoslav communists in a coali- tion with nationalist partisans, fought and took con- trol of the country with little outside help. The economic organization of each country provides, perhaps, the most vivid contrast. In 1949, Yugoslav-Soviet rela- tions were severed. (For a developed discussion of this breach, see: Claudin, The Communist Movement: From Comintern to Cominform, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1975, Vol. 2, Chapter 7.) Shortly after, Yugoslav communists opted to decentralize the country's economic and political systems. Results of this pro- gram included the establishment of workers' councils, an influx of western capitalist investments, and the setting up of trade relations with the capitalist world system. On the other hand, Polish communists continued to develop Poland's economy along the lines of the highly centralized Soviet model. This position is most often held by sectarian political groups. See: The Peoples' Democracies: Are They Socialist States? by Viox Ouvriere, 1966, a SPARK pamphlet. 31 10. ll. 12. l3. l4. l5. 16. 17. 32 M. Lavigne in The Socialist Economies of the Soviet Union and Europe, London; M. Robertson, 1974, presents a clear summary of the various classification schemes purposed. This is expanded in both the introduction and concluding chapter of Braverman's Labor and Monopoly Capital, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974. These points can also be found in Critique of the Gotha Programme by Marx and State and Revolution by Lenin. This perspective in no way implies the inevitability of unidirectional development; that socialist countries could never revert to capitalism. "Peaceful Transition from Socialism to Capitalism?" Monthly Review, 15, 11, 1964, p. 569-590, discusses this possibility. "Labor becomesexternal to the worker, i.e., it does not belong to his essential being; ... in his work, therefore, he does not affirm himself but denies him- self, does not feel content, but unhappy and does not freely develop his mind and physical energy, but morti- fies his body and ruins his mind." Karl Marx, Early Writings, (translated and edited by T.B. Bottomore), New York: Pathfinder Press, 1964, p. 125. For a discussion of this type see either R. Garundy, The Crisis in Communism: The Turning Point of Socialism, New York: Grove Press, 1970, or the July-August 1975 special issue of Monthly Review. David M. Gordon, "Capitalist Efficiency and Socialist Efficiency," Monthly Review, 3, 19, 1976, p. 19-39. D. Gordon, 1976, p. 27. This presentation of the 'Free Labor'/'Collective Labor' dichotomy is simplified for reasons of clarity. Although not self-identified as such, the article "On the Nature of the Soviet State" by Ernest Mandel (New Left Review, 108, p. 23-47) could be seen as an example of the rfree labor' view of communism. The work of Charles Bettlehiem provides a clear elaboration of the 'collective labor' orientation. There are many important elements involved in increasing the level of the development of the forces of production. However, increasing automation of the production process is often stressed in the 'free labor' view as a crucial element in reducing socially necessary labor time. An alternative understanding of the apparent fluctuations 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 33 in the writings of Marx, Mao, and Lenin might be found by tracing the development of these ideas in the context of the writers' political struggles. A project of this type, though beyond the scope of this paper, could pro- vide valuable insights into the historical origins of these two views. Evaluation of the economic models of development under socialism is beyond the scope of this paper. Again, see the work of B. Ward or W. Brus for development of this subject. See Sweezy's articles "Socialism in Poor Countries," Monthly Review, Vol. 28, No. 5, October 1976, p. 1-13, for a summary and critique of this approach. The concept of human nature is given only a cursory treatment in this paper. For a more developed presenta- tion of Marx's concept of human nature and a discussion of the resulting transformation under capitalism, see B. Ollman, Alienation: Marx's Concept of Man in Capitalist Society, London: Cambridge University Press, 1975. Joachim Israel, Alienation: From Marx to Modern Sociology, Boston: Allyn and Bacon, Inc., 1971, p. 57. "The real essence of man is not an abstraction inherent in each particular individual. The real nature of man is the totality of social relations." (Marx, 1964, p. 45) "The production of life, both of one's own labor and of fresh life in procreation now appears as a double rela- tionship: on one hand as a natural, on the other as a social relationship. By social we understand the co- operation of several individuals no matter under what conditions, in what manner and to what end ... Thus it is quite obvious from the start there exists a materi- alistic connection of man with one another, which is determined by their needs and their mode of production, and one which is as old as men themselves." (Marx, 1964, p. 50) "We presuppose labor in a form that stamps it as exclu- sively human. ... But what distinguishes the worst archi- tect from the best of the bees is this, that the archi- tect raises his structure in imagination before he erects it in reality. At the end of every labor process, we get a result that already existed in the imagination of the labourer at its commencement. He not only effects a change of form in the material on which he works, but he also realizes a purpose of his own that gives the law to his modus operandi, and to which he must subordinate his will." (Marx, Capital, Vol. I., New York: Charles Kerr and Co., 1926, p. 18) 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 34 Karl Marx, 1926, Vol. I, p. 173. For further elaboration of this separation process, see Ollman, Alienation, especially pages 133 and 134. Mandel and Novack, 1976, p. 22. Credit must be given here to Joachim Israel. In his book, Alienation: From Marx to Modern Sociology, he clarifies the structural processes of alienation. A quote from Braverman underlines the importance of this distinction: "While the social division of labor subdivides society, the detailed (manufacturing) divi- sion of labor subdivides humans, and while the sub- division of society may enhance the individual and the species, the subdivision of the individual, when carried on without regard to human capabilities and needs, is a crime against the person and against humani- ty." (Braverman, 1974, p. 73) By 1971 approximately 85% of all productive capital was state owned in Poland. (Mesa-Lego, Comparative Socialist Systems, Pittsburg: University of Pittsburg Press, 1975, p. 408) In 1964, 90% of all Yugoslave in- dustry was socialized. (Staar, Communist Regimes in Easiern Europe, Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, 1977, p. 185) Admittedly, a large portion of the agricultural sector of the economies in both the coun- tries remains in private hands, but for the purposes at hand this sector is relatively unimportant. Although the threat of being out of work is minimized in Poland, workers still compete for higher paying jobs. Unemployment is ever present in Yugoslavia. In addi- tion, both Poland and Yugoslavia utilize material in- centive programs. Braverman, 1974, p. 19. Zukin, Beypnd Marx and Tito: Theory and Practice in Yugoslav §9ciali§m, London: Cambridge University Press, 1975, p. 56. These functions are paraphrased from the Fundamental Principles of the 1950 Law found in Workers Manage Factories in Yugoslavia, by Marshall Tito, p. 47-55. H. Watchell examines the results of this legislation in Workers'Management and Workers Wages in Yugoslavia. The extent that workers participate in these structures is considerable. In 1968, roughly 6% of the people working in enterprises of more than 70 people were members of workers' councils. (International Institute 37. 38. 39. 40. 41. 42. 43. 44. 45. 46. 47. 35 for Labor Studies Bulletin, No. 9, 1972, p. 144). Why did Yugoslav communists undertake this decentrali- zation process? Three sets of explananthmushave been suggested in answer to this question. The official pronouncements underline decentralization as an impor— tant element in the road to communism; as a first step toward the withering away of the state. Political historians emphasize decentralization as a way rival political factions were placated enabling Yugoslav communists to maintain power without Soviet support. The third set of explanations centers around the need for investment capital Yugoslavia faced after breaking from the Soviet Union. It is argued that the economic decentralization process was undertaken to attract capital from the capitalist world. In all probability, a combination of these rationals was considered by the Yugoslav communists in their decision to decentra- lize the economy. It is estimated that during this period, 25% of the Polish industrial labor force were members of a union. (Kolaja, A Polish Factory, University of Kentucky Press, 1960, p. 2). Sturmthal, "The Workers' Council in Poland," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 14, No. 3, April 1961, p. 380-81. In 1953, 40% of the national income was allotted to accumulation. (Sturmthal, p. 381). The incidents at Poznan and the Zeran automobile plant are perhaps the most well known examples of these strikes. Sturmthal, p. 386. The number of active workers' councils in 1957 exceeded 5,600 (Statistical Yearbook, 1959, p. 393). As early as 1958, Communist party leaders were making distinctions in their speeches between supervision and administration by the workers. For a discussion of some of these conflicts see: Rawin, "Social Values and Managerial Structure: The Case of Yugoslavia and Poland," Jourgal of Comparative Admini- stration, 2 No. 2, August 1970, p. 131-160. "The New Law on Workers' Controls," Polish Perspectives, No. 3, 11, March 1959, outlines this new formation. After the passage of this law, no new workers' councils were formed. 48. 49. 50. 51. 52. 53. 54. 55. 36 For example, the workers' riots of 1970 helped oust Gomulka from power and install Gierek. For more recent accounts, see: David Lascelles, "Poland," Financial Times Survey, Friday, December 5, 1975, p. 33 and Flora Lewis, "Many Poles Term Unrest Far Deeper Than Economic," The New York Times, Wednesday, January 26, 1977. This is not surprising considering both the short period of their independent existence and the strin- gent information controls present in the Soviet Bloc during this period. The only exception to this statement is reported in a study by J. Kolaja, who found workers' councils to be perceived as the most influencial by 57% of the workers queried, with the director perceived as most influencial by only 35% of the workers surveyed. (Kolaja, 1965, p. 34). Kolaja, 1960, p. 109. In fact, in Yugoslavia, workers' councils play an important part in the selection of the director and may also vote on the renewal of the director's contract. Kolaja, 1960, p. 108. Managerial and white collar personnel accounted for 37% of these Boards in Kolaja's study. (Kolaja, 1965, p. 17). The data for this observation are found in the descrip- tive accounts written by Kolaja on both countries. LIST OF REFERENCES LIST OF REFERENCES Braverman, H., Labor and Monopoly Capital, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974. Brus, Wlodzimierz, The Economics and Politics of Socialism, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1973. Brus, Wlodzimierz, "Income Distribution and Economic Reforms in Poland," Politico, 39(1), 1974, p. 5-28. Brus, Wlodzimierz, Socialist Ownership and Political Systems, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1975. Claudin, Fernando, The Communist Movement: From Comintern to Cominform, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1975. Fromm, E., Socialist Humanism, Garden City, New York: Double Day Press, 1965. Garundy, R., The Crisis in Communism: The_TurningPoint of Socialism, New York: Grove Press, 1970. Gordon, David M., "Capitalist Efficiency and Socialist Efficiency," Monthly Review, 3, 19, 1976, p. 19-33. Israel, Jonchim, Alienation: From Marx to Modern Sociology, Boston: Allyn and Bacon, Inc., 1971. Kolaja, Jiri, A Polish Factory: A Case Study of Workers' Participation in Decision Making, Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1960. Kolaja, Jiri, Workers' Councils: The ngoslav Experience, London: Tavistock Pub. Ltd., 1965. Lavigne, M., The Socialist Economies of the Soviet Union and Europe, London: M. Robertson, 1974. Mandel, E. and Novack, G., The Marxipt Theory of Alienation, New York: Pathfinder Press, 1976. Mandel, E., "On the Nature of the Soviet State," New Left Review, 108, 197, p. 23-47. Marx, Karl, Capital, New York: Charles Kerr and Co., 1926. 37 38 Marx, Karl, Early Writings (ed. T.B. Bottomore), New York: Pathfinder Press, 1964. Mesa-Lago, Carmelo, Comparative Socialist Systems, Pittsburg: University of Pittsburg Press, 1975. Obradovic, Josip, "Participation and Work Attitudes in Yugoslavia," Industrial Relations, 9, 2, 1970. Obradovic, Josip, "Workers' Participation: Who Participates?" Industrial Relations, 14, 1, February 1975, p. 32-44. Ollman, Bertrand, Alienation: Marx's Concept of Man in Capitalist SoEIety, London, Cambridge University Press, 1975. Ouvriere, Viox, The People's Democracies: Are They Socialist States?, A Spark Pamphlet, 1966. Rawin, John, "Social Values and Managerial Structure: The Case of Yugoslavia and Poland," Journal of Comparative Administration, 2, 2, August 1970, p. 131-160. Rus, Velyiko, "Influence Structure in Yugoslav Enterprise," Industrial Relations, 9, February 1970. Staar, R., Communist Regimes in Eastern Europe, Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, 1977. Sturmthal, Adolf, "The Workers' Councils in Poland," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 14, 3, April 1961, p. 380-394. Sweezy, P. and Bettleheim, C., On the Transition to Socialism, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1971. Sweezy, Paul M., "Socialism in Poor Countries, Review, 28, 5, October 1976, p. 1-13. Monthly Tito, Josip Broz (Marshall), Workers Manage Factories in Yugoslavia, Beograde, 1950. Watchel, H., Workers' Management and Workers' Wages in Yugoslavia: The Theory and Practice of Participatory Socialism, Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1973. Ward, Benjamin N., The Socialist Economy: A Stpdy of Organizational Alternatives, New York, 1967. Zukin, Sharon, Beyond Marx and Tito: Theory and Practice in Yugoslav Socialism, London: Cambridge University Press, 1975. , "Peaceful Transition from Socialism to Capitalism?" Monthly Review, 15, 11, 1964, p. 569-590. 39 "The New Laws on Workers' Controls," Polish Perspectives, 3, 11, March, 1959. , "Workers' Participation in Management, Country Series: Yugoslavia (No. 9)," International Institute for Labour Studies Bulletin, No. 9, 1972, p. 129-173. General References Adizes, Ichak, Industrial Democracy: Yugoslav Style, New York: The Free Press, 1971. Barton, Denitch, and Kadushin (eds.), Yugoslav Opinion Makers, New York: Praeger, 1973. Bethell, Nicholas, Gomulka, His Poland and His Communism, London: Longmans, Green and Co. Ltd., 1969. Bloch, Jozef, Labor Legislgtion and Social Instructions in Poland, London, 1972. Bogdan, Kavcic, Velyido Rus, and Arnold Tannenbaum, "Control, Participation, and Effectiveness in Four Yugoslav Industrial Organizations," Administrative Science Quarterly, 20(3), 1971, p. 163-168. Boggs, Carl, "Marxism, Prefigurative Communism, and the Problem of Workers' Control," Radical America, Vol. II, No. 6, November 1977 - February 1978, p. 99-122. Bogosalijevic, M. and Pesakovic, M., Workers' Management of a Factory in Yugoslavia, Beograde, 1959. Broekmeyer, M.J. (ed.), Yugoslav Workers' Self-Management, (proceedings of a symposium held in Amsterdam, 7-9 January 1970.), Dordrecht, Holland: D. Reidel Pub. Co., 1970. Dahl, Robert A., After The Revolution?, New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970. Deleon, Aser, "Workers' Management," Annals of Collective Economy. Deutsch, Andre, Communist Economy Under Change: Studies in the Theory and Practice of Markets and Competition in RussIa, Poland, and Yugoslavia, London, 1963. Djilas, Milovan, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System, London: Thames and Hudson, 1957. Djilas, Milovan, The Unperfect Society: Beyond the New Class, New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, Inc., 1969. 4O Dunn, William N., "The Economics of Organizational Ideology," Journal of Comparative Administration, February 1974, p. 395-431. Faber, Bernard Lewis, Social Structure in Eastern Europe, New York: Praeger, 1976. Farkas, Richard Paul, Yugoslav Economic Development and Political Change: The Relationship Between Economic Managers and Policy Making Elites, New York: Praeger, 1976. Feiwel, Georg R., Industrializationiand Planning Under Polish Socialism, New York, 1971. Galli, Giorgi, "Bureaucracy Under Fire," Problems of Communism, 16 September 1966, p. 31-35. Garson, G. David, On Democratic Administration and Socialist Self-Management: A Comparative Survey_Emohasizing the Yugoslav Experience, London: Sage Publishing, 1974. Gordon, 0., Themes of Poverty and Underemployment, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1970. Gorupic, D. and I. Paj, Workers' Self Management in Yugoslav Undertakings, Zagreb, 1970. Gorupic, Prago, ed., The Enterprise and the Development of Yugoslav Economic Systems. Grzybowski, Kazimierz, "Polish Workers' Councils," Journal of Central European Affairs, XVII, October 1957. Harman, Chris, Bureaucracy and Revolution in Eastern Europe. Hollander, Paul, "Observations on Bureaucracy, Totalitarianism, and the Comparative Study of Communism," in Fredrick J. Fleron Jr., Communist Studies and the Social Sciences, New York: Rand McNally and Co., 1969. Horvat, Branko, An Essay on Yugoslav Society, White Plains, New York: International Art & Science Press, Inc., 1969. ‘ Hunnius, G., Garson, G. David, and Case, John, (eds.), Workers' Control: A Reader on Labor and Social Change, New York: Random House, 1973. Jerovsek, J. and Mozina, J., Self-Management in Working Organizatipp from the Point of View of Efficiengy and Democracy, 7th World Congress of Sociology: September 1970. 41 John, P.M., Marx on Alienation: Elements of a Critique of Capitalism and Communism, Calcutta: Minerva Publishers, 1976. Kardelj, Edward, "The Basic Tasks in the Further Development of Socialist Relations," Review of International Affairs, 11 May 1960. Kordasgewski, Jan, "A Polish Contribution to Job Evaluation for Non-manual Workers," International Labor Review, Vol. 100, No. 2, August 1969, p. 141. Lewis, Flora, The Polish Volcano, London: Secker & Warburg, 1959. Ludlow, Howard T., "The Role of Trade Unions in Poland," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 90, No. 2, Summer 1975, p. 315-325. Marek, Edward, "Workers' Participation in Planning and Management in Poland," International Labor Review, Vol. 101, No. 3, March 1976, p. 271. Marinovic, Milos and Zvonko,Simic, The Yugoslav Trade Unions, Belgrade, 1970. Matejko, Alexander, Social Change and Stratification in Eastern Europe: An Interpretive Analysis of Pgland and Her Neighbors, London: Praeger Publishers, 1974. Mesa-Lago, Carmelo, "A Continum Model to Compare Socialist Systems Globally," Economic Development and Cultural Change, 21 July 1973, p. 573-590. Mieczkowski, Bogdan, Personal and Social Consumption in Eastern Europe: Poland, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and East Germany, New York: Praeger Press, 1975. Milenkovitch, Debra D., Plan and Market in Yugoslav Economic Thought, New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971. Pateman, Carole, Participation and Democratic Theory, London: Cambridge University Press, 1970. Piekalkiewicz, Jaroslaw, Communist Local Government: A Study of Poland, Athens, OhIO: Ohio University Press, 1975. Roberts, Paul Craig, Alienation and the Soviet Economy; Toward a General Theoryiof Marxian Alienation, Organizational Principles and the Soviet Economy, Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 1971. 42 Selucky, Radoslav, Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe: Political Background and Economic Significance, New York, 1972. Stojanovic, Peter, Industry: Worker Management in Practice, Belgrade: Export Press, 1966. Stojanovic, Svetozar, Between Ideals and Reality: A Critiqpe of Socialism and Its Future, New York: Oxford Press, 1973. Taylor, J., The Economic Development of Poland, 1919-1950, Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1952. Verba, Sidney and Shlabad, Goldie, "Workers' Councils and Political Stratification: The Yugoslav Experience," American Political Science Review, Vol. 72, 1978, p. 80-95. Vladimin, Dedijer, Tito, New York: Simon and Schuster, 1953. Vuskovic, "Social Inequality in Yugoslavia," a paper presented to the Conference of the Croation Communist Alliance, January 1973. Wilczynski, J., Profit, Price and Incentives under Socialist Economic Planning, London: McMillan, 1973. Wiles, Peter, Political Economy of Communism, Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1962. Zauberman, A., Industrial Develppment in Czechoslavakia, East Germany and Poland, 1937-1956, Oxford Press, 1958. Zinner, Paul E. (ed.), National Communism and Popular Revolt in Eastern Europe, New York: Columbia University Press, 1956. , Congress of Workers' Councils of Yugoslavia, Edition of the Central Council of the Confederation of Trade Unions of Yugoslavia, 1957+. "Poland: Recent Social Security Legislation," International Labor Review, Vol. 100, No. 2, August 1969, p. 167. , "Polish Workers and Party Leaders: A Confrontation," New Left Review, Vol. 72, March-April 1975, p. 35-53. , The Program of the League of Yugoslav Communists, London: International Society for Socialist Studies, 1959+. 43 "The Ruling Class in the Sejin and at Work: Worker Self-Management in Poland," World Marxist Perspectives, February 1973, p. 91-101. , Twenty Years of Polish Peoples' Republic, Warsaw, 1964. ‘1i1111111111111l“