a! a ,nEa i. .. . «an. .
3.9%"? 1...: firifim. v r...
I 21‘ u. 3.17.3- '- 2.00.... v .. .
54.5; o .4 .thl . 9P1! . .. V 1
PK»: 3mm ”Rxfiéfl .. mwrnm .V
2 . ... .... a hfihk
. K3135. .
. ”.5, bk .
.. V
.) Vii
It-
.
.V .32. 1......
mm}.
V .
. mmk .
1H9.
t
.
1!: 1. "kvfiiy {Ii}: \1’.i\¢(.
V l‘:).1\..lrlt3n§.lv‘lor7\
I
V.
. . , . V .. \ . , . . \. .. E)?!
. V 1. . i r. x . . . :3.1..1V4$1.5\‘~9dti.u211(svxti¥yi>fl.t.¢n,
:. : a; V. . . . . . V . :..\3.l!17.)1.5.¢1) 1v>xVII..;.!4’)II?1-ielflrlm.x
.V. h.\ \ . p l . >
. so)
t V r I I
. > ‘1 ‘VZI‘.|S€’§?.'% 4"“
V 11!]!!! )xxifis \\1‘\\1\.\ tgé‘li
. r1 1:3; V 990... k .. y . V V . .V. {Itag‘z‘l‘ihiixtlr .uV‘ixVRHY1 ’1|\J\(I\ NV 00
F .(fiOl‘ ~ ' rt? ’N . n. l I? ‘knkfihu V» 5 V .. . J... $ T. . a, 4. .. . . .u» x .V ‘ . . 1 V. A ..$\1l1)|. ‘1, V. .1197??? W1.§2§\2’1¢z7" 31
.o. . .. . . . p 11111 9.3%,) I... y! '1)?- t‘ \\S
u .1... a. .3151 z. .3 $82 at L, . 1. . . . ,. . . . . . . V 5;. Vizzzzzflli: lzqiiizai
5 I I. 3 4 ii, M. 1 . .. . .. , t V .. . x. I!) {2.431.}... {(5415)}.
”fig: Kart :. I)fi!,.2fiflu\d \} n. 3‘ {‘11 .1\ l}: V 1 . . . V .. .a)1l\mns|§::ai Silt“: 35>)1.J.fllsz\.l‘ iv.
uohiinucsolg9r.‘nfivofi g.) \l. 5.5.1.901 .gnlg}fii.wu\ . . V V . V V V . . 1.2‘33dufllixvssr 2.1:!"911. .. “.1134 lull-1.25..
;.§}r.7 viii... I. u...“ .3 .. mattizfittfi Q1353 s.4.i...:fiu.\ri3{\1\x\1 . . ..i\.{l~£)\.uas§i .§}¥Vv{y{simii.1 it“ x
» Walrtél. oil! th’iltc "14,19: )1}. 512%.". {\211‘... Aral“: (\s 33.3.); L . \ T V V , .6 .. V . , . waanangv AgiV\ .
v c. .Klt ! :v o 2! i . 553‘ .... . . iiihflkll‘fiths! i2). . . V . :1 36.911111 312$] 3
"Huva...v|.cv-V§ 5.2.7!!! \\). \s ulfixti 0.5 «(If . 5333. c1273 fixtfii . . . r . . | 11¢. aszEH‘qw‘itvquv v k. Q!
.WVTov‘IIhI-tll‘v‘t V ‘2 VJ. .. . I; 2.. ETIHQW. u)" 1' 1531: #4-" \ . . . 3151‘ vu.l.\i$ .v)... tin” Vi“ 31.)) . 3‘13}?! . -
1.£.fivi 03.39. nu} 3“\ § 1! 11¢! 19...? ‘33‘211 . .i1n‘l1131! 11g.%\IJ)\.¥I niS‘fll\f¢aJ\?vl.I| 1 V 537
I: In! .10) 33: fix Hull“). .
I n g 'II' C ’0‘} ~ V % . "IO\|.I“ A\‘\ni\\‘4..\ ‘llfiL u.» 7 l
V . .13 $(txxrllx ‘3)...15w‘1!» L
- xfl.r..))|\. ‘ «fiflflnhnhq‘nfllz
3.1.1 lvv. . .c fiuufiuuuu). .. . . H .411)... ; \
‘1 \..\ .t .. . u . 3 V . .3. .
.
.1 (5; (115.31 It!!!) I. \\\\\\\
avg}? 11131.1:7» (.uki .. u. .
.. . is. V. ilizinvnzi
3‘11}? .‘l‘vi! 1.171..»
. . n ( 316% an}:
\ V 1‘ i
I; . .u . It!!! \ 1| III]! ‘ A
V 77!.l3f‘tVinquwtlilnllunflflnicnflo, )il. .
r .ut‘~ '1. 'tr’.’ {Ii I {3 'i' ‘I l
4riu).\)v.!¢ul‘.|).fl:nl.l|‘iv v. 1‘1! it 1": cu“. 3.135114 1
...:I\“!V. Vii.‘v.|?lfsb(‘.vbo .
\l
. . .
. gr. x%£\3§§£§
31‘giiii'vl3vi w} I V . fr
, (IV-s $\\1L.I.\(.tn!‘}rlu|i)\ 1511\‘i‘8'tl‘i - .V . I 31“) 41 ill) 1!? it'll
V Igl‘fig 11, . A i. . 19.5,;
V 15. . I In I It; ‘ I’ll“. .15...
l n 1 iii, , V I. 7‘ 4g: 11“},‘iii1if {
Isl-Irv... it \1}...|"fl!l.|.o. 2 . . 7:515:35 £1;
.L .‘Ve'ntrkai .Ldrvbkttlt) .Elti‘:
. ' . 51’ 3.4. If'y..4l’§\’1tkriifv“if\ob§ All.
. .l-1L'alx1ll'lxt" p.?.LID\A|7-Du¢.§\z It!)
.. .\V.Ol«!..r‘0‘.:oAIIVlrlllfiili .4 .iitviif
. .1". |.b‘..l7r\.b.f.!.‘v1!u.l Pagfg .
.'\"
T‘OH’
.zé'u'fll 31,.
) V
‘MC:
. .. .Vv bA\l
A »\2\..~{u \L \I er VLA .
K .. ..‘\ \\bu\)¢u\ I..rILr,1u\¢4\L\sX 1’5}. v
‘. A. v \ L 7». 1 I
i .\ 5.5!}... £1-Vi-¥\£t:¥«n.\ri’1%EE-¥
.. . :l.utz¢.1vullllz ..?.t..\.hx.cl.5f .\E53.~A§PE2.L1.O{.|;J.)}IJ.L»
. .. 1:331}: . . .. s .l «$511.;lszéliti..»3.r¢.u>ly!. \ . V
‘ l 2,: Frzkxti 2s.....t....4, :1 5.1-: .2
: -1..- ,1: 1?- I
A « “HM. r , a 2 . x.
.. , _ a .
x3. (ka V
> \l|\fi“.~V \\.v- lit-L... _
. .IIIIVO’VVIV . :1, (n. .V LI. uV.—1.7.vtv I! V . .w .
Mb”... 5.35) r V" valatfauszx .uu‘fL-i .‘ . V . ....|.l\$Lr. . \ V x I?! .5 I
.Ilvllvbt,Ev.L...: III. . .
. ii... z , . k: Mir... . .iK. - “FEE
lufiialyr ll.‘
.2 nth. .\
$45-- :.........5.F..«Pinwgmrimflmm‘wfifi .
3 1293 10067 3825
T// n‘: «‘1‘ 1’. .
‘2 T/Ai - .V 4___"/
.mflls
LI ‘33 I ~‘3 "' w
3"" 43 4'2. (i ‘ _
V5.
P515 1' ‘ A
“ ‘3‘ 11‘1”) 3‘ ‘. Vt-ysfi‘ 1
.nb.i‘alfu 11,-}; Q’I-f__".'~*)
V-) ‘ W’
U nivcm fay
'
I
-.’
m. . ‘w‘~'v.r‘
This is to certify that the
thesis entitled
AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE BEEF-CATTLE
INDUSTRY OF URUGUAY
presented by
Luis O. Coirolo
has been accepted towards fulfillment
of the requirements for
Ph.D. degree in Agricultural
Economics
WWK/%EZ¢Z/
Major professor
Date January 4, 1979
0-7 639
OVERDUE FINES:
25¢ per day per it.
RETURNIIG LIBRARY MATERIALS:
Place in book return to renov 2
charge fro. circulation records
. -v __4 T‘M"'fifi“ii.fi.mm v-rr-w-v-WV‘w—j
AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE BEEF-CATTLE
INDUSTRY OF URUGUAY
By
Luis O. Coirolo
A DISSERTATION
Submitted to
Michigan State University
in partial fulfillment of the requirements
for the degree of
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
Department of Agricultural Economics
1979
ABSTRACT
AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE BEEF-CATTLE
INDUSTRY OF URUGUAY
By
Luis O. Coirolo
Beef production has always been and still is a keystone in the
Uruguayan economy. During the last thirty years, Uruguay has experienced
a slowdown in the growth rate of the cattle sector. Research is
needed to find means of accelerating growth in the cattle industry in
order to continue economic growth at the national level. Substantial
government intervention in the beef-cattle industry of Uruguay exists.
This study provides descriptive and quantitative information which
might help in the improvement of public policy decisions, particularly
in the area of beef-cattle supply. However, domestic beef consumption
and beef exports were also analyzed.
The objectives of the study were:
l. To obtain descriptive knowledge of the dynamics of the beef-
cattle economy
2. To identify and quantify the effect of the most important
factors affecting the beef-cattle economy
3. To model econometrically the structure of the Uruguayan beef—
cattle industry, in particular, to investigate the critical relation-
ships affecting (a) the number of cattle supplied, (b) the meat yield
per animal slaughtered, (c) the amount of beef internally consumed,
Luis 0. Coirolo
(d) the amount of beef available for exports, and (e) the investments
required to increase beef production
The study was based on annual time-series data, and ordinary least
squares was the statistical procedure used. For the estimation of the
supply of cattle for slaughter, a polynomial distributed lag model was
developed.
The main conclusions of the study were as follows:
1. The most important variables affecting the number of cattle
supplied for slaughter were the farmers' beef price, particularly when
lagged one year, the number of hectares of improved pasture in produc-
tion, and the weather. The effect of beef prices on beef-cattle supply
for slaughter is negative for two years and positive for the next four
years. The number of hectares of improved pasture is positively
related to the supply of cattle; and the weather, expressed in terms
of an index of pasture conditions, has a negative influence on the
number of cattle supplied in the short run, since better weather
conditions allow for the finishing of cattle that could otherwise have
been sold before fattening.
2. The meat yield per animal slaughtered is positively related
to weather conditions as they affect pasture conditions and negatively
related to the slaughter extraction rate. Both variables are related
to the availability of roughage. In Uruguay, raising and fattening
cattle is done by direct grazing, and it appears that, in Uruguay, the
extraction rate more than a productivity index has been an indication
of lack of sufficient roughage to get all the supplied animals to the
finished stage.
Luis O. Coirolo
3. The only exogenous variable with a statistically significant
parameter affecting domestic beef consumption was found to be the
retail price of beef, which is controlled by the government. The
price of beef substitutes and the income level parameters were not
statistically different from zero. The level of beef consumption is
very high in Uruguay; in addition, practically no beef substitutes
exist in the country.
4. The demand for exports is affected by the total quantity of
beef supplied and by the level of internal consumption. The export
price does not play the role that would be expected in the case of an
uncontrolled market. This finding suggests that the quantity of beef
exported is the surplus above the level of domestic consumption.
5. Pasture improvement has been practically the only investment
in cattle production during the period of the study. Phosphate fer—
tilizer subsidies and a negative real rate of interest on government
loans were the most important variables affecting the annual gross
investment in hectares of improved pasture.
This study also estimated the total beef supply that would result
under different assumptions of government policies in relation to beef
prices and subsidies on investment inputs. From this analysis and
from the conclusions of the study, policy implications are drawn.
Dedicated
to
My Family
11
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
During the time of my graduate studies at Michigan State Univer-
sity, I have been helped by several individuals and institutions. It
is difficult for me to express my appreciation adequately to all of them.
Nevertheless, I want to express my deepest gratitude to my Major
Professor, Dr. Warren Vincent, for his deep human involvement in the
creative guidance, intellectual stimulation, and encouragement given
to me throughout all my graduate program. I want also to express my
sincere appreciation and gratitude to Dr. Darrell Fienup, who was
instrumental in getting the financial assistance needed for my graduate
study, who provided important guidance at the earlier stages of my
program, who gave me encouragement, and who served on my Guidance and
Thesis Committees. It was Dr. Fienup who gave the initial impetus to
my work. I also want to thank Dr. Stanley Thompson, who served as my
Thesis Advisor. Dr. Thompson's dedicated help made possible the formu-
lation and the conclusion of this thesis.
Thanks are also extended to Dr. Anthony Koo, Dr. Vernon Sorenson,
and Dr. Derek Byerlee, who served on my Guidance Committee, and to
Dr. Harold Riley, who served on my Thesis Committee.
To my fellow graduate students, in particular to those in Chittenden
Hall, with whom I shared all these years at MSU, a special thanks.
My gratitude also goes to the Comision Honoraria del Plan Agro-
pecuario in Uruguay, the Ford Foundation, and the Agency for International
Development for the financial support they provided during my studies
at Michigan State University.
I also want to give special thanks to Mrs. Ann Carroll for her
committed and careful editing of my thesis and to Mrs. Cathy Cooke for
her dedicated and expert typing job. They both worked without time limit
to make possible finishing this thesis.
To all these people-~Muchas gracias!
iv
TABLE OF CONTENTS
List of Tables .
List of Figures
Chapter
I
II
III
INTRODUCTION
Introduction
The Problem . .
Purpose of the Study . . .
Objectives of the Study .
Procedures . . .
Relevance of the Study
Chapter Organization
THE AGRICULTURAL SECTOR .
Background Conditions of the Country
General Characteristics of the Agricultural Sector.
Economic Importance
Agricultural Land .
Farm Size and Land Tenure .
Summary .
THE BEEF-CATTLE INDUSTRY
The Cattle Stock
Cattle Breeds .
Production
Internal Consumption
Exports .
Summary .
oowmth—I
l2
l2
l5
I6
20
21
21
22
23
32
36
38
Chapter
IV METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH . . . . ..........
The Economic Model
Supply
Beef Supply Equations . . . . . .
Derived Demand for Roughage . . .
Demand . . .....
Review of Beef Demand Studies I I I
Beef Demand Equations . .
The Statistical Model . . . . I I I I I
Equations and Variable Definitions
Equations . . .
Variable Definitions
Estimation Procedure
Distributed Lag Model . . . . . . .
Test of Statistical Estimates . .
Summary ..... . . . . . . .
V STATISTICAL ANALYSIS AND RESULTS
The Estimated Supply Equations . . .
Number of Beef Cattle Slaughtered .
Meat Yield per Animal Slaughtered .
The Derived Demand for Roughage . .
Testing the Supply Equations . .
Beef Supply Forecasting ........
The Estimated Demand Equations . .
Beef Demand for Internal Consumption
Beef Demand for Exports . .
VI SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
Supply Analysis . . . .....
Review of Beef Supply Studies . . .
00000
Number of Beef Cattle Slaughtered I I I
Meat Yield per Animal Slaughtered .
Demand Analysis . . . .
Policy Implications . .
Recommendations for Further Research
APPENDIX .
BIBLIOGRAPHY . .....
vi
Page
39
39
41
43
48
50
51
52
56
57
59
59
6O
62
65
67
68
7O
7O
71
79
81
83
91
95
95
100
102
102
103
105
107
108
112
114
123
Table
2.1
LIST OF TABLES
Gross Domestic Product at 196l Prices
(In thousands of Uruguayan Pesos) .
Total Exports of Uruguay
(In millions of U.S. dollars) .
Percentage Distribution of Land Use .
Percentage Distribution of Total Number of Holdings
and Total Land Area by Various-Sized Holdings .
Some Productivity Indicators by Size of Farm
Ratio of Cattle Stock, Population, and Cattle
to Inhabitants . . . . . . . .
Percentage Distribution of Cattle by Size of Holdings
Improved Pasture Production of Beef at the Farm Level
Number of Producers Assisted by the Plan Agropecuario
(1961—74) .
Beef Production, Consumption and Exports
(Carcass Weight Equivalent) .
Quality of Steers, Cows and Total Animals Slaughtered
(September 1970) . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Average Slaughter per Month .
Breakdown of the Export Price of Beef (USS/Ton) .
Beef Exports by Type of Product
(Percent of Total Exports)
Page
14
15
17
18
19
22
24
27
28
29
3O
31
35
37
Table
5.1
Page
Parameter Estimates for Unconstrained and Constrained
Second and Third Degree Polynomial Lag Models
(Five- Year Lag) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
Parameter Estimates for Unconstrained and Constrained
Second and Third Degree Polynomial Lag Models
(Six— Year Lag) . . . . ...... . . . . 74
Simple and Cumulative Price Elasticities of Total
Slaughter . . . . . . . . . . . . . ..... . . . . 76
Short and Long-Run Price Elasticities of Slaughter
Estimated in Previous Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
Ability to Forecast Turning Points
Supply Equations
(Quantitative Measure of Graphical Analysis for
Supply Equations) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
Theil' s U Coefficient of Inequality for the Supply
Equations . . . . . 90
Forecast of Beef Supplied Under Different Assumptions
of Beef Price Increases and of Interest Rate
(000 M.T.) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Domestic Beef Demand Equations . . . . . . . . . . . 97
Price and Income Elasticities of Demand from
Different Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
Cattle Stock, Slaughter, Average Weight, and Total
Beef Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
Internal Beef Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
Export Price of Beef, Exchange Rate, Farmers' Beef
Price, Price of Wool, Price of Phosphate Fertilizer,
and Interest Rate on Loans for Improvement of Pastures 117
Retail Prices of Beef, Pork, Chicken, and Fish and
Consumer Price Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
Number of Hectares of Improved Pasture: Created,
Existing, and in Production
1956-75
(000 Hectares) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
viii
Table Page
F Data Used in Figures 5.1, 5.2, and 5.3 . . . . . . . 120
G Data Used in Figure 5.4 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
H Forecast of Total Beef Supply Under Different Price
Assumptions for Prices of Beef, Fertilizers, and
Interest Rate
(MT 000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
ix
LIST OF FIGURES
me m:
4.1 Diagram of Economic Interrelations in the Beef-Cattle
Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
5.1 Number of Beef Cattle Slaughtered . . . . . . . . . . 86
5.2 Meat Yield Per Animal Slaughtered , , , , , , , , , , 87
5.3 Total Beef Supplied . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
5.4 Annual Gross Investment in Improved Pastures , , , , 89
5.5 Actual and Forecast Total Beef Supply (In thousand
metric tons) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
CHAPTER I
INTRODUCTION
Introduction
Uruguay relies heavily on the agricultural sector and particularly
on beef production as a source of food for its population, as inputs
for its industry, and as the basis of the foreign exchange needed for
essential imports. Due to the fertile land endowment, excellent
climate, and good water supply, beef production has always been and
still is a major element in the Uruguayan agricultural economy.
During the first fifty years of this century, Uruguay enjoyed a
high level of income from her agricultural exports, mainly as a con-
sequence of a high international demand for beef and wool.1 An increase
in world beef supply and a slowdown in the growth rate of the cattle
sector started a process that showed, particularly after the end of
the Korean War, the intricate economic link between the cattle sector
and the Uruguayan economy as a whole. It appears that it is necessary
to regenerate the original growth rate of the cattle sector and to
increase beef exports in order to continue economic growth at the
national level.
1Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, CIDE-—Sector Agropecuario, Estudio Economico
y Social de la Agricultura en el Uruguay (Montevideo, 1967).
2
The intent of this study is to contribute to the growing stock
of knowledge concerning the dynamics of the Uruguayan cattle sector.
In particular, the study attempts to provide needed descriptive and
quantitative information about some of the important relationships
among the variables affecting this sector.
The Problem
The economic depression of the 19305 and the disruption of inter-
national trade greatly reduced Uruguay's earnings derived from the
export of livestock products (beef and wool). For the period on
which this study focuses (1956-75), the livestock sector contributed,
on the average, more than 80 percent of the country's annual total
exports.2 During this difficult period, Uruguay began a pronounced
policy of industrialization via import substitution. At the same time,
it further emphasized policies promoting income redistribution and
social welfare. These policies, as well as most other policy measures
directed toward achieving economic development, were largely financed
by the livestock sector;nminly through export taxes. This tendency
was particularly accelerated at the beginning of the 19505.
The role played by the livestock sector, and the beef—cattle
industry in particular, in support of the rest of the economy has been
guided by strong government intervention. This intervention has been
substantial at all stages of the industry: in production, processing,
internal consumption, and exports. However, in general, government
intervention has not contributed to the solution of the problems of
2Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Objectivos y Metas del Sector Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972).
3
the industry3 which occur at various levels. The main problems at the
production level are 1) low beef-cattle productivity level based on
extensive grazing of native pastures, 2) existence of foot-and-mouth
disease, and 3) lack of adequate supply of pasture throughout the
year with the subsequent seasonality of beef production.4 The most
important shortcomings at the level of the meat packing industry are
1) low sanitation standards, which are not acceptable to some of the
major importing countries, 2) lack of adequate cold storage capacity
to compensate for the seasonal fluctuations in production, and 3) low
value added of processed meat.
Internal consumption of beef in Uruguay has been traditionally
very high. In addition, the lack of beef substitutes for consumption
and the important political power of the urban population determined
that the price of beef has always been a political issue in which the
consumer has been the winner. During the period 1956-75, prices to
beef producers and consumers were maintained at artificially low
levels.
Beef exports accounted for almost 40 percent of total export
earnings in the last five years of the study.5 Beef export performance
greatly affects the country's balance of payments, has important implica-
tions for monetary and fiscal policies, and in general affects the
3Brannon, Russell H., “The Role of the State in the Agricultural
Staggation of Uruguay" (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin,
1967 .
4Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Cuarto Proyecto de Desarrollo
Ganadero del Uruguay (Montevideo, 1971).
5Hunting Technical Services and Oficina de Programacion y Politica
Agropecuaria, Agricultural Diversification Study (Montevideo, 1976).
4
country's economic growth and development possibilities.
Purpose of the Stugy
Given the importance that beef production has for the Uruguayan
economy and its role in the country's development, it is necessary to
determine the factors that have been affecting the possibilities of
growth of the beef-cattle sector and the extent of their importance.
From among the various problems that the beef industry faces, this
study focuses particularly in the analysis of beef supply. However,
analyses of demand of beef for internal consumption and of the avail-
ability of beef for exports are also included.
In addition to the artificially low prices of beef, producers face
uncertainty in terms of other government policies regarding export
taxes, exchange rates, production subsidies, price of inputs, credit,
etc. These uncertainties have complicated the producers' decision
making and created unfavorable conditions for investment in the sector.
In light of these problems, this thesis studies past characteristics
and trends of the beef-cattle sector which could be relevant to
achieving the goal of increasing beef production and exports.
Objectives of the Study
The overall objective of the study is to investigate the struc—
ture of the Uruguayan beef-cattle industry in order to suggest means
of accelerating growth in this sector through improved public policy
decisions in the areas of beef production, domestic beef consumption,
and beef exporting. To accomplish this major objective, the following
more specific objectives are set:
5
1. To obtain a descriptive knowledge of the dynamics of the beef-
cattle economy, hence a better understanding of the determinants of the
demand for inputs, beef supply schedules, internal consumption, and
availability for exports
2. To identify and quantify the effect of the most important
factors affecting the beef-cattle economy. Emphasis is placed on
estimating the effect of relevant factors affecting the production,
consumption, and beef-export subsystems, rather than on evaluating
the whole beef-cattle economic system simultaneously
3. To model econometrically the structure of the Uruguayan beef-
cattle industry, in particular, to investigate the critical relationships
affecting a) the number of cattle supplied, b) the meat yield per
animal slaughtered, c) the amount of beef internally consumed, d) the
amount of beef available for exports, and e) the investment required
to increase beef production and the price of needed inputs
Procedures
The study is based on annual time—series data. Heavy reliance is
placed on the use of aggregate data that were obtained from secondary
sources. Nevertheless, some nonnumeric, primary information is also
used.
Secondary data were obtained from the Ministry of Agriculture and
Fisheries (the Direction of Agricultural Economics, the Livestock
Development Plan, the National Research Center, and other agencies),
the Central Bank, the Bank of the Republic, the Ministry of Industries,
the National Meat Board, and the Association of Owners of Meat Packing
6
Plants. Data were also obtained from publications, both in Spanish
and English, from the Foreign Agriculture Organization, International
Bank of Reconstruction and Development, European Economic Community,
and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Some first-
hand information was obtained by visiting farmers, processors, and
decision makers in the government when the author was working in
Uruguay and during the period of data collection in the field at the
beginning of 1978. More specific information about the data collected
will be presented in the Appendix.
The econometric model consists of the following relationships:
four behavioral equations (number of beef cattle slaughtered, meat
yield per animal slaughtered, domestic demand for beef, and export
demand for beef) and two identities (total beef supply=number of beef
cattle slaughtered times meat yield and total beef demand=beef demand
for internal consumption plus beef demand for exports).
During the period of the study, severe and largely unpredictable
government controls were operative, mostly with respect to prices. Con-
sidering the extent to which beef prices may be regarded as predetermined
and due to the recursive estimation of beef supply, a single equation
approach for the statistical estimation of the equation parameters was
selected. Ordinary least squares is the statistical procedure used.
For the estimation of the supply of cattle for slaughter, a polynomial
distributed lag model is developed.
7
Relevance of the Study
It is expected that the results and policy implications of this
study will be of use at least for the following policy-making bodies
of Uruguay:
1. The Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries. This Ministry is
responsible for agricultural production and agricultural policy formu-
lation. It determines the areas and level of government intervention
in the sector
2. The Bank of the Republic. This agency is in charge of pro-
viding financial assistance to the farmers contributing to the imple-
mentation of the agricultural policy decided by the government
3. The Livestock Development Project, which provides technical
assistance to beef producers and is in charge of the introduction of
new technology into the sector
4. The Central Planning Office, which is responsible for the
overall planning of the economy and the allocation of resources between
the different sectors
5. The Ministry of Industry and Trade which is responsible for
the agencies in charge of domestic supply and promotion of foreign
markets
6. The Central Bank, which, in coordination with the Ministry
of Finance, decides on matters of monetary policy, influences the low
price of beef when trying to maintain a low inflation rate, and manipu-
lates the exchange rate
7. The Uruguayan beef producers themselves, who are instrumental
in investing in new technologies to increase productivity
8
Chapter Organization
This introductory chapter explained the motivation for this
research, the purpose and objectives of the study, as well as its
relevance in policy making.
Chapter II discusses the agricultural sector of Uruguay and some
of the problems that it has faced during the period of the study and
at the present.
Chapter III is devoted to a description of the Uruguayan beef-
cattle industry.
Chapter IV discusses the methodological approach of the study.
The economic and statistical model is presented.
Chapter V explains the statistical analysis and provides the
empirical results. The estimated supply and demand equations are
reported and discussed.
Chapter VI contains the summary and conclusions, the policy implica-
tions of the study, and recommendations for further research.
CHAPTER II
THE AGRICULTURAL SECTOR
General Background of the Country
Uruguay, situated between southern latitudes 30 and 35, bordered
by Argentina and Brazil, occupies an area of 187,000 square kilometers
or 72,172 square miles, qualifying as one of the smallest countries in
South America. Almost 90 percent of this area can be used for agricul-
tural production, for it has good climate, soil, and water supply.
Thus Uruguay must be considered as one of the world's most favored
nations agriculturally.
During the first part of the twentieth century, Uruguay was regarded
as a model of democracy, stability, and social justice. With its fer—
tile soils and small population, the country was able to build an
economic system based on the agricultural sector, most specifically the
livestock sector, exporting beef and wool. These exports provided high
income levels and extensive social benefits for the population, which
is literate, culturally homogenous, and largely urban.
The population of Uruguay is about 2.8 million, with half living
in the capital, Montevideo, about 300,000 living in rural areas, and
the rest living in cities in the interior of the country. The rate of
growth of the population is 1.2 percent per annum. It can be said that
all the Uruguayan population is of European origin, since at the time
of the conquest, the native population was very small, estimated at
10
about 5,0001 and was exterminated or absorbed by the European immigrants.
The level of education is high-~the adult literacy rate is 91 per—
cent; primary school enrollment was 94.5 percent as of 1970. The national
per capita income was U.S. $890 in 1974.2
As mentioned earlier, until the mid-19505 Uruguay was regarded
as a model of democracy, stability, and social justice in clear contrast
with other Latin American countries. In terms of health services, Educa-
tion, social security,and level of food consumption,Uruguay could be
compared favorably with many developed countries. Until the 19305,
the economic growth was primarily based on the extensive production of
livestock products for export. In 1930 meat accounted for 46 percent
of the total exports, wool 26 percent, and hides 11 percent, the rest
being crops 11 percent and other exports 6 percent.3
The economic depression of the 19305 represented a collapse of
the world market for Uruguay's traditional exports. Another develop-
ment phase started then, with a process of productive structure diver-
sification through industrialization via import substitution. This
process was further emphasized due to the disruption of world trade
during World War II. These policies were largely financed with taxes
on agricultural exports; trade barriers were created to protect the
1Oddone, Juan Antonio, Economia y Sociedad en el Uruguay Liberal (Monte—
video: Ediciones de la Banda Oriental, 1967).
2International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Economic
Memorandum on Uruguay (Washington, D.C., 1975).
3Universidad de la Republica, Instituto de Economia, E1 Proceso
Economico del Uruguay (Montevideo, 1969).
11
local industry. The production of import substitutes that Uruguay
could produce at a competitive level was rapidly reached. The result,
as in other Latin American countries, was the development of high-cost
industrial production that could compete only in the protected domestic
market.
The end of the Korean War brought about severe declines in the
prices of Uruguay's principal exports, and this decline reinforced the
previous government proclivity to develop industry at the expense of
agriculture. Without maintaining its agricultural production and ex-
ports, particularly the ones from the livestock subsector, Uruguay was
not able to sustain either the industrial sector which had been created
nor to support the welfare policies which had been implemented. Con—
sequently, Uruguay, which had grown at over 5 percent per year during
the period 1944-56, has grown at less than 1 percent during the 20 years
(1956-75) considered in this study.4 Per capita income has declined
over this period by a total of roughly 10 percent in real terms.
The economic deterioration process led to a spread of social con-
flicts over economic claims and even to the appearance of one of the
most sohpisticated guerrilla movements in Latin America. This movement
was destroyed in 1972-73 when military forces seized power. This was
the end of almost 100 years of continuous multiparty democracy in
which the armed forces played no political role.
4Universidad de la Republica, Facultad de Ciencias Economicas, Uruguay
Estadisticas Basicas (Montevideo, 1976).
12
General Characteristics of the Agricultural Sector
Uruguay's temperatures place it in the temperate zone, there being
only slight variations within its territory. The average temperature
for the warmest month, January, is about 23° Centrigrade (73 degrees
Fahrenheit), and the average temperature for the coldest month, July,
is about 10° Centigrade (50 degrees Fahrenheit). Frost occurs 10 to
20 times during winter. The average rainfall for the last 50 years was
1,070 millimeters, occuring uniformly throughout the year.5 The topog—
raphy generally is slightly undulating with very few hills and no moun-
tains. The highest elevation in the country is less than 600 meters
(2,000 feet) above sea level. The vegetation originally was low grasses
directly usable in livestock production. Water is plentiful from
numerous rivers and small water courses. The soils, in general, are of
medium to high fertility, but about 20 percent are superficial rocky
soils.6 According to the last census of 1970, 90 percent of the soil
is used for livestock production, 8 percent is utilized principally in
extensive agriculture, 1 percent is forested, and 1 percent is used
for more intensive crops such as horticultural crops, orchards, and
vineyards. In the last general agricultural census of 1970, Uruguay
had 8.5 million beef cattle, mainly Hereford; there were about 500,000
dairy cattle, mainly Holstein. Uruguay also has 19.8 million sheep,
5Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, E1 Plan Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972).
6Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, CIDE--Sector Agropecuario, Estudio Economico
y Social de la Agricultura en el Uruguay, (Montevideo, 1967).
13
principally Corriedale. There were 460,000 horses and 383,000 pigs.7
Economic Importance
During the period of the study, as is shown in Table 2.1, the
contribution of the agricultural sector to the Gross National Product
has been around 15 percent, with the contribution of the industrial
sector being 23 percent, and the service sector 57 percent. The Uru—
guayan population was around 2.8 million in 1975, 40 percent of it being
the working population (1,100,000). The national census of 1966 indicated
that only 190,000 (17 percent of the working population) were working
in agriculture. The industrial sector employed 27 percent of that
population and the service sector 56 percent of it.8 The census of
1970 showed a further decrease to 132,200 in the population working in
the agricultural sector. The contribution of the agricultural sector
to the national economic output and to employment has been low. These
two economic indicators appear to follow similar patterns to those of
developed countries, but this is only apparent since Uruguay, like
other Latin American countries, has not been able to finance and absorb
in a productive way the urbanization process. This has led to a hyper-
trophy of the service sector, in particular the public one.
When other indicators are analyzed, such as the participation of
agriculture in the external trade sector and as a source of raw material
for the local industry, the importance of the agricultural sector for
7Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Departamento de Estadistica
Division Censos y Encuestas, Censo General Agropecuario 1970
(Montevideo, 1973).
8Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Objectivos y Metas del Sector Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972).
14
TABLE 2.1
Gross Domestic Product at 1961 Prices
(In thousands of Uruguayan Pesos)
1956 1961 1966 1971 1975
Agriculture 2,482 2,193 2,429 2,839 2,715
Industrya 3,527 3,423 3,683 3,956 4,350
Construction 1,004 850 703 800 854
ServicesP 8,497 9,200 9,375 9,732 9,907
Total G.D.P. 15,510 15,666 16,190 17,327 17,826
Source: Banco de la Republica and Banco Central.
aIncludes mining.
bIncludes commerce, transportation, utilities, housing, financial,
government, and other services.
the Uruguayan economy appears clearly. For most of the twenty years of
the study (1956-73), more than 90 percent of the total Uruguayan exports
have been from the agricultural sector. In 1956, 99 percent of the
country's exports were livestock or other agricultural products. Only
in two years (1974 and 1975), as can be seen in Table 2.2, the relative
contribution of the agricultural sector to exports declined. This was
due to a reduction in the international price of beef and to an impor-
tant increase in the exports of leather manufacture. The livestock
subsector has been the most important contributor during the period of
the study, contributing more than 80 percent of the country's total
exports. These figures show that the external sector of Uruguay is
heavily dependent upon agriculture and particularly on beef and wool
production. The performance of the livestock sector determines what
15
will be the volume of foreign exchange available for development.
Additionally 40 percent of the gross industrial product comes from
industries that use agricultural inputs.9
Total Exports of Uruguay
TABLE 2.2
(In millions of U.S. dollars)
Total Agri. Livestock Total Agri. Contribution of
Exports Products Products Sector Agri. Sector
Exports (%)
1956 215.7 31.9 180.0 212.9 99
1961 174.7 12.4 157.1 169.5 97
1966 185.8 14.9 161.6 176.5 95
1971 196.6 25.5 154.9 180.4 92
1973 327.6 31.8 268.3 300.1 92
1974 381.3 52.6 269.5 322.1 85
1975 384.9 71.3 216.2 287.5 75
Source: Oficina de Programacion y Politica Agropecuaria with data from
Banco de la Republica and Banco Central del Uruguay.
Agricultural Land
Uruguay's land area is about 18.7 million hectares (46.2 million
acres) of which about 16.6 million hectares (41.0 million acres) could
be used for livestock or agricultural production.
basis, this represents roughly 6 hectares per person.
On a per capita
A more favorable
9Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Objectivos y Metas del Sector Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972)
16
man/land ratio is found only in Australia and Argentina. Nevertheless,
very little productive investment has been made in the Uruguayan agri-
cultural sector.
Most of Uruguay's agricultural land (around 80 percent) is in
native pasture. Improved natural pasture, although increasing since
the 1956 census, was still a very small percentage of the total area
10
(9.3 percent) in 1970 and about 10 percent in 1975. Only 8 percent
of the agricultural land is devoted to cultivated crops. (See Table 2.3.)
Farm Size and Land Tenure
More than 55 percent of the land (60.9 percent in 1970) consists
of farms with more than 1,000 hectares (2,471 acres) owned by only 5
percent of the producers. On the other extreme, 73 percent of the far-
mers own only 6 percent of the land.
The National Agricultural censuses of 1956, 1961, 1966, and 1970
show no important changes in the pattern of land distribution; however,
there is slightly more concentration of land ownership as indicated by
the decrease in the number of holdings and decrease in the land area
of small farmers. (See Table 2.4.).
Some authors have indicated that the concentration of the land in
big farms constitutes a structural barrier to investment and to the
ability to respond to price incentives. This indicates that an inverse
10International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Uruguay Third
and Fourth Livestock Development Projects (Washington, D.C., 1976).
17
TABLE 2.3
Percentage Distribution of Land Use
1956 1961 1966 1970
Pasture
Natural Pasture 81.1 81.5 79.6 77.5
Artificial Pasture-
annual 2.7 2.1 3.0 2.5
permanent ---— 0.9 1.9 2.2
Improved Natural
Pasture 1 6 2.3 3.1 4 6
Scrub 2.6 2.7 2.5 2.9
88 0 89.5 90 1 89 7
Crop Land
Cereals 7.3 5.7 5.0 5.6
Oilseeds 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.6
Other 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.8
9.8 7 9 7.1 8 0
Forestry Plantations 0.7 0.8 0.9 0.9
Other Use and Unproductive
Land 1.5 1.8 1.9 1.4
TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Sources: General Agricultural Censuses—-1956, 1961, 1966, and 1970.
18
TABLE 2.4
Percentage Distribution of Total Number of Holdings
and Total Land Area by Various-Sized Holdings
._—__—
Size a Total Number of Holdings % Total Land Area %
(hectares) 1956 1961 1966 1970 1956 1961 1966 1970
1-99 75.1 74.8 73.4 72.9 9.5 8.8 6.0 5.9
100-499 16.9 16.5 17.3 17.3 19.9 18.9 17.7 17.6
500-999 4.0 4.3 4.4 4.7 14.8 15.4 15.1 15.6
1000-2500 2.7 3.0 3.4 3.6 22.6 23.5 26.0 26.9
2500 & more 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.5 33.2 33.4 35.2 34.0
TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Sources: General Agricultural Censuses 1956, 1961, 1966, and 1970.
a1 hectare = 2.47 acres.
relationship exists between size of holdings and productivity.”’12
But practically no research has been conducted in this important area
even though such knowledge is very important for policy makers when a
restructuring of the landholding pattern is considered.
When some productivity indicators,such as birth, mortality, and
stocking rates of cattle and sheep, crop yields, and use of fertilizer,
are analyzed, there is no evidence that large holdings are less pro-
ductive than small ones. The information of Table 2.5 has been obtained
HUniversidad de la Republica, Instituto de Economia, E1 Proceso Economico
del Uruguay (Montevideo, 1969).
12Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, CIDE--Sector Agropecuario, Estudio Economico
y Social de la Agricultura en el Uruguay (Montevideo, 1967).
19
.onmp .mamcmu Fmgzppzuwgm< ”moczom
N.emw F.Nmm o.o F.0e m.F o.m o.~e 8.0 m.mm _eeoe
m.~oo m.mmo.~ m.m N.oe N.P m.~ m._e o.o o.mm egos ace oom.N
o.Fem w.moo._ m.m m.mo e._ e.N e.FN o.o ©._e oom.~-ooo._
m.mee e.omm N.o N.oe m._ _.m ~.me o.o m.em amm-oom
P.N~m o.emm m.o m.oe m._ o.m m.ee w.o G.Nm mme-oo_
m.emm m.~mm _.m a.mm m._ w.m N.me m.o _.mm mm -_
eeou bees: aeewwmmoz cwwmm emuemwuuuz sewwwmmoz emwmm LeMLMWMHuz mnwmm_wwuwu Ammeeeumxv
mgmuumz can upmw> nogo mumcm mpppmu em unwogwm wnmm
Egon yo m~_m x5 mgogm0wvcH zuw>wuuacoea meow
m.N m4m
aov mczwrzovem< x wwgmumcmm we o_cmumw:wz use mmccwu mu chowumz opauwumcH ”mugaom
mm _om Fe _Fe em ooe em Fem me __N 255355;; ea waste eez
- - ANV AFNV Amy A_¢v on Aoev Aev Am_v Ameoemmweeouv Smog wepem
- 1 ANV Am_v Ao_v ANNV Aoev Aaev ARV Ammv _e>au
gmusvoga mmxm» uuwcwvcm
_ m 5 mm as m__ 8_ mo, PP om eoeee~w_eeeeeeeou co emou
mm aow em owe me mpm ox owe em _eN 25535525 5e 55525 macaw
mN “we em mmm __ ee m. aw mm No, cemeez mucosa museums pee:
mucmpa mcmxuma
1 1 1 1 m Pm m cm N o_ yam: Eogu mm_wm co mmxoh
5
55 Amy Aomv ANV Aemv ANV Ae_v ANV Ae_v Aev “Nev wees: co
Ae_v Aemmv Aav Ammv A__v Amev AN_V Aomv Ae_v “mov pee: :0
m_ 0mm N_ m__ mp Na 4_ Na m. mm mexe» eeeaxm
cop mmm._ cop eoo.P oo_ coo.F oo_ ewe oo_ owe ee_ea “coax“
a a e w a a a w a a
mmap .>oz N~m_ .>oz Fem, so: cum. .eeo amm_ an:
Acop\wmav $mmm we move; ucoaxu any we czovxmmgm
m.m m4mou
ms x mumz H mm#
mz 1
apaasm 111111. mcowuwucou
mummz
Legeo
yo oowcm
_weuem
chgmucH
xmauag
:_ osouwH 1mv mmww we mucoqu
gmszmcou powwa wmmm
.pnmmoqmw. F. a
co_uaszmcou
A11111¢v
mumz 1 Amli
mgzummm mumew_u
x_aa=m wmwm _cu0h
:o_ucm>couc o_u:w>couc
ucoE:Lm>oo acme:Lm>oo mmeeucsou
. nguo
An Comm
9 mo »_aa:m
mpmou mc_umxng new
cowumNPpm_gum=ucH
mucmpa asexuaa Ham:
momeucsou // mowguczou
1111111111111 mcwugoaefi measuTGmnam , mcwugoaem
:owucm>cmgca :_ msoucH wmom cw
pcmaccm>oo emanmcou we «owe; \ :owp:w>gwucu
m_nmmoamwo unmEcgm>ou
41
to the consumers. During some months of the year, in some years, the
government also determines the quantity offered for local consumption
establishing ”vedas,“ or periods "without meat.”
In the external market, the National Meat Board must approve all
foreign sales made by meat-packing plants. The National Meat Board
also determines weekly minimum prices at which contracts may be
accepted. The quantity of beef exported is affected indirectly through
fixed beef prices and directly when ”vedas” are imposed to increase
the amount of beef available for exports. In the following section,
the theory of supply and demand is reviewed to see its application to
the particular conditions of the Uruguayan economy.
Supply
Supply response, or quantities of output, and its relationship
to resource inputs and product prices appear to be one of the basic
problems in Uruguay's agriculture. Supply research is necessary to
provide additional information to policy makers, enabling them to make
improved policy formulation. This supply response research should
indicate the direction and the magnitude by which the relevant variables
influence supply.
Traditional economic theory suggests that the market supply of
beef or any other product is a ceteris paribus relationship. That is,
the quantity supplied will vary as the price of the product changes,
other factors affecting supply holding constant. The other factors
that can affect supply are substitution in production, price of inputs,
technology, weather, price of other products, etc.
42
Up to this point, theory is used to assist in identifying the
relevant variables that enter the behavioral relationship and in identi-
fying the direction of their influence. The magnitude of their influence
will be considered later in this study. (See Chapter V.)
The market supply relationship can be expressed in functional
form as follows:
05 = f (Pp,PI,PSP,T,W, . . . )
where:
Q5 = quantity supplied
Pp = price of product supplied
PI = price of inputs
PSP = price of substitutes in production
T = technology
W = weather
Economic theory suggests that the price of the product at hand
will have a positive effect on quantity supply. The price of inputs
and the price of substitutes in production are expected to have a nega—
tive effect on quantity supplied. In the case of technology, a posi-
tive effect on quantity produced is also expected. The weather or
climatic conditions could have positive or negative effects on produc-
tion. Nevertheless, if a climatic or weather index is developed, it
could be determined which index values would affect quantity supply
positively and which values would affect it in a negative way.
The properties or assumptions underlying the supply of output
functions are based on comparative static economics and included in
43
theory of profit maximization in a competitive market. These proper—
ties are presented in many books, and they are not repeated here.]’2’3
Review of Beef Supply Studies
Before using the previous concepts for the analysis of the supply
of beef in Uruguay, a short review of beef supply analyses performed
in Uruguay or in countries with similar production conditions is pre-
sented. Unfortunately, practically no interest was displayed in
Uruguay in the analysis of beef-cattle production trends or the causes
of stagnation of the sector until the whole economy became affected in
the middle of the 19505. Since then, few studies have been carried
out; most of them are of a descriptive nature. Some quantitative
analyses have been conducted which have attempted to explain the effect
of single variables on quantity of beef supply. The most relevant of
those studies are reviewed.
Probably the first of the descriptive studies was conducted in
1950 by a mission at the Food and Agriculture Organization and the
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.4 This study
group was invited by the government of Uruguay to analyze the livestock
sector and to suggest policies and programs that might help to increase
1Nicholson, Walter, Microeconomic Theory (Hinsdale, Ill.: The Dryden
Press, 1972).
2Cohen, Kalman and Cyert, Richard, Theory of the Firm: Resource Alloca-
tion in a Market Economy (Newark: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1975).
3Lloyd, Cliff, Microeconomic Analysis (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin,
Inc., 1967).
4International Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the Food
and Agriculture Organization, Agricultural Development of Uruguay
(Rome: The United Nations, 1951).
44
beef production. As mentioned in Chapter III, this study recognizes
the lack of adequate roughage supply as the most important factor
affecting livestock, particularly beef-cattle production.
Between 1960 and 1970, the government of Uruguay with the finan—
cial support of the IBRD regarded the same variable as the most impor-
tant. It directed the first two livestock development projects of
Uruguay for the improvement of grazing and arable land resources
through phosphate fertilization and for practices of pasture improve-
ment. (See Chapter III.)
In 1970, the appraisal of the third Livestock Project of Uruguay
by the IBRD5 shifted the perspective followed from the beginning of
the 19505. Policy issues, such as the price of beef to producers and
consumers, were seen at this stage as more important than technological
issues in affecting the development of beef-cattle production.
A major descriptive study was published by the Ministry of Agricul—
ture in 1967.6
In this analysis the following variables were mentioned
as affecting the production of Uruguayan beef cattle: (1) the technology
(namely roughage production); (2) farmer beef prices; (3) climatic con-
ditions; (4) price of substitutes in production (sheep wool was identi-
fied as the main production alternative to beef cattle); (5) price of
inputs (namely the price of phosphate fertilizers); (6) technical
assistance to the farmers, and (7) agricultural credit.
5International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Appraisal of
Third Livestock Project of Uruguay_(Washington, D.C., 1970).
6Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, CIDE--Sector Agropecuario, Estudio Economico
y Social de la Agricultura en el Uruguay (Montevideo, 1967).
45
Other studies conducted later by Brannon,7 Fletcher and Merrill,8
and Coirolo9 generally concurred that the variables previously men—
tioned are the most important factors affecting beef production in
Uruguay. Virtually no quantitative analysis of the Uruguayan beef
industry has been conducted to date.
10 11
The Planning Office of the Ministry of Agriculture,
12
Coirolo,
and the Livestock Development Project studied the return on invest-
ment in improved pastures in the livestock sector of Uruguay. The
three studies concluded that the number of hectares of improved pastures
in production has an important effect on beef supply at the farm level.
Using regression analysis to study the effect of pasture improve-
ment on beef supply, von Oven13 concluded that the introduction of
this new technology had a positive effect on beef—cattle production.
7Brannon, Russell H., ”The Role of the State in the Agricultural Stag-
nation of Uruguay'I (Ph D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin, 1967).
8Fletcher, L. and Merrill, H., The Uruguayan Agricultural Sector:
Priorities for Government Policies, Investment Programs and Projects
(Washington, 1970).
9Coirolo, Luis, ”Factors Affecting the Uruguayan Trade of Livestock
Products” (M.S. Plan 8 paper, Michigan State University, 1976).
10Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Cuarto Proyecto de Desarrollo Ganadero
(Montevideo, 1971).
HCoirolo, Luis, ”Rentabilidad Marginal de los Mejoramientos de Campo
en 23 Predios Seleccionados” (Tesis de Ingeniero Agronomo, Montevideo,
1972).
12Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, El Plan Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972).
13von Oven, Roderick, ”Impacto de los Pasturas Mejoradas Sobre 1a
Produccion Ganadera en el Uruguay,“ Comision Honoraria del Plan
Agropecuario, Anuario 1975 (Montevideo, 1975).
46
According to his results the improved pastures accounted for 64 percent
of the variation in beef production between 1961 and 1974.
Pimentel,14 in his study "Mathematical Models for the Agricul-
tural Sector of Uruguay," analyzed the factors affecting cattle stock
and the supply of animals for slaughter. He concluded that the most
important factor affecting both cattle stock and slaughter supply is
the expected beef price. The price expectations, he stated, are based
mainly on past prices.
Jarvis,'5 using annual data for the period 1960-76, through
regression analysis estimated two equations to explain aggregate
cattle slaughter. One equation estimated tons of beef produced, and
the other estimated gross number of animals slaughtered. In both
cases he found that the most important variables affecting beef supply
were cattle stock in the previous year and the farmer beef price in
the same year.
Different Argentinian time-series studies on beef supply16’17’18’19
found that the "expected" price of beef based on past beef prices,
14Pimentel, R., et al., Modelos Matematicos Para el Sector Agropecuario
Uruguayo (Montevideo: Banco de la Republica, 1976).
15Jarvis, Lowell, "The Economic Determinants of Uruguayan Beef-Cattle
Herd and Slaughter Levels 1960-1976“ (Unpublished paper, Montevideo,
1977).
16Iver, Raul E., ”The Investment Behavior and the Supply Response of the
Cattle Industry in Argentina” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of
Chicago, 1971).
17Jarvis, Lowell 3., “Supply Response in the Cattle Industry, The Argen—
tine Case, l937/38--1966/67” (Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology, August 1969).
18Reca, Lucio G., ''The Price and Production Quality Within Argentine
Agriculture 1923—1965“ (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago, 1967).
47
particularly in the previous year, is one of the most important
variables affecting the supply of beef. According to these studies,
farmers expect the prices of the last period of production to prevail
in the current period. In their supply equations, other variables
such as price of grains (substitute in production), weather conditions
(proxy for pasture conditions), cattle stock, and time (as proxy for
technological improvements) were also included. Most of these studies
concluded that only a few variables can explain most of the variation
in beef supply.
Other studiesZO’ZI’22
have divided the supply of beef into two
components: (1) number of cattle slaughtered and (2) average weight
per animal slaughtered. Otrera analyzed the number of cattle slaughtered
as a function of the farmer price of beef in current and previous years,
the price of grains, and time. The average weight per animal was con-
sidered to be a function of the farmer beef prices, rainfall conditions
in the previous year, and time. The equations containing the mentioned
variables were selected largely because of their ”high” explanatory
DOWEY‘ .
19Nores, Gustavo A., ”Structure of the Argentine Beef Cattle Economy:
A Short Run Model, 1930-1970” (Ph.D. dissertation, Purdue University,
1972).
20Otrera, Wylian R., ”An Econometric Model for Analyzing Argentine Beef
Export Potentials” (Ph.D. dissertation, Texas A&M University, 1966).
2INores, Gustavo A., “An Econometric Model of the Argentine Beef-Cattle
Economy'I (Master's thesis, Purdue University, 1969).
22Kulshreshtha, S.N., Wilson, A.G., Brown, D.N., An Econometric Analysis
of the Canadian Cattle-Calves Economy (Saskatoon, Canada: Department
of Agricultural Economics, University of Saskatchewan, 1971).
48
Beef Supply Equations
Economic theory of supply, previous descriptive and quantitative
studies particularly in Uruguay and Argentina, and the author's know-
ledge of the Uruguayan beef industry provides the basis for specifying
the supply functions in this empirical analysis. The supply model will
consist of two behavioral relationships and one identity. This approach
consists of dividing the supply of beef into two components: (1) number
of beef cattle slaughtered and (2) meat yield per animal slaughtered.
The identity determines total beef supply which is the product of the
two components.
Beef cattle supplied is postulated in the following,equations:
(l) NBCS = f(FBC, CS, IP, IPC, PW)
(2) MYPAS = f(FBP, IPC, IP, SERA)
(3) TBS = (NBCS) x (MYPAS)
where:
NBCS = number of beef cattle slaughtered
FBP = farmer beef prices
CS = cattle stock
IP = number of hectares of improved pastures in production
IPC = index of pasture conditions
PW = price of wool
SERA = slaughter extraction rate
Beef production is then postulated to be a function of several
factors: (1) farmer beef prices; (2) cattle stocks, which previous
studies indicate affect the number of cattle slaughtered; (3) improved
pastures, which have been the only technological change that was
governmentally promoted during the period of the study; (4) index of
49
pasture condition. For all practical purposes, livestock production
in Uruguay is based exclusively on direct grazing. As a consequence,
weather conditions affect the grazing capacity of the pastures, in-
fluencing beef production. This index, constructed with climatic
indicators (rainfall and temperature) is a proxy for the availability
of pastures or grazing capacity. (5) Price of wool. In Uruguay, beef
and sheep are produced together. At the country level, wool is the
only substitute in production. In studies of the Argentinian beef
industry, the price of grains, particularly wheat, was included as a
substitute in production. From this point of view, the Argentinian
situation is different from that in Uruguay. In most of the Argentinian
beef producing areas, grains (mostly wheat) are real substitutes in
production for beef. However, of the 16.6 million hectares used in
livestock production in Uruguay, only 1.0 to 1.5 million are used in
extensive agriculture. The total area potentially usable for grain
23 In
production in Uruguay does not exceed 3.0 million hectares.
addition, livestock producers do not have machinery or the ability to
assume the risk involved in grain production. Great price fluctuations
have determined that the area traditionally used with annual crops has
not exceeded 1.5 million hectares. (6) Slaughter extraction rate.
The extraction rate is defined as the total number of animals slaughtered
divided by the total number of animals in stock. This variable is not
included in any of the studies reviewed. In the case of Uruguay,
stocks are reduced before the winter, due to reduction in pasture
supply. The relationship between animals sold and total stock does
23Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Los Suelos del Uruguay,
Su Uso y Manejo (Montevideo, 1967).
50
(in the author's opinion) affect beef production. In particular, it
is proposed that the slaughter extraction rate is related to the meat
yield per animal slaughtered. Additionally, an identity (the product
of the number of beef cattle slaughtered times meat yield per animal
slaughtered) is needed for determining total beef supply.
Derived Demand for Roughage
The most important and practically only input used in cattle pro-
duction is roughage. The agricultural frontier has long been reached
in Uruguay, and the increase in pasture productivity is the way to
increase this input availability. Grains are not generally an economic
alternative in Uruguay. The following derived demand for additional
roughage will be estimated:
AGIIP = f(FBP, IR, PFF)
where:
AGIIP = annual gross investment in improved pastures expressed in
number of hectares
FBP = farmer beef prices
IR = interest rates on credit
PFF = price of phosphate fertilizer
Farmer beef prices are believed to be an important variable
affecting the decision to invest in improved pastures. At the farm
and country level, cattle and sheep graze together, but the improved
pastures have been and still are managed only with cattle.‘24’25’26
24Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, E1 Plan Agropecuario
(Montevideo, 1972).
25Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, Anuario 1975 (Montevideo, 1975).
26Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, Anuario 1976 (Montevideo, 1976).
51
As mentioned in Chapter III, 98 percent of the beef producers who made
investments in improved pastures received credit assistance. It is
hypothesized that the interest rate of those credits affects farmers'
investment decisions. In value terms, phosphate fertilizers represent
more than 70 percent of the inputs to be used in improving pastures.
Accordingly, fertilizer price is believed to have an important effect
on the number of hectares of pastures improved.
Demand
The market demand relation describes the market behavior of con-
sumers when buying a product. It indicates the amount of a product that
consumers in a particular market will be willing and able to buy at
different prices. This behavioral relationship between quantity demanded
and prices holds under a certain set of assumptions.
As in the case of supply, demand relationships are formulated, in
general, under the ceteris paribus condition. This implies that the
demand relationship explains changes in quantity demanded as the price
of the product changes, all other factors that affect the demand of
the product holding constant. Some of the major factors affecting
product demand are price of substitutes in consumption, income level,
population, tastes and preferences, inflation, etc.
The demand relationship can be expressed in functional form as
follows:
d-
Q - f(Pp1PS,I.P0P,TP, . . . .)
where:
0d = quantity demand
P = price of product demanded
52
.0
1|
price of substitutes in consumption
5
I = income level
POP = population
TP = tastes and preferences
As in the case of the supply relationship, the properties or
assumptions underlying the demand function are those of comparative
static economics based on the theory of profit maximization for a firm
in a competitive market. Studies listing these properties have already
been cited.
Economic theory indicates a negative relationship between the
quantity demanded of one particular product and its price. The prices
of the products that are substitutes in consumption are directly
related to the quantity demanded of the product that is being studied.
A similar direct relationship holds for population and income.
Review of Beef Demand Studies
It is unfortunate that no quantitative analysis of beef demand has
been performed for Uruguay. There are, however, descriptive studies
indicating some of the factors affecting the demand for Uruguayan
27-35
beef. There is general agreement in these descriptive studies
27Brannon, Russell H., ”Uruguay: A Focus on Agriculture“ (Unpublished
paper, 1966).
28Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, CIDE--Sector Agropecuario, Estudio Economico y
Social de la Agricultura en el Uruguay (Montevideo, 1967).
29Brannon, Russell H., ”The Role of the State in the Agricultural Stag-
nation of Uruguay“ (Ph D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin, 1967).
53
that the high level of beef consumption in Uruguay is the result of
the government setting the farm level price of beef at artificially
low levels. The price of beef in Uruguay is substantially lower than
the international price (see Chapter III).
These studies single out the low farm price levels, even though
no quantification is presented as the most important determinant of
internal demand. It is also mentioned that the lack of beef substitutes
in consumption is another reason for the perpetuation of the high
levels of beef consumption. Prices of beef substitutes such as chicken
and pork are higher in Uruguay than in the international market.
Income and population are mentioned as affecting positively the level
of beef demand. Most studies state, however, that both population and
consumer income are not very important in affecting demand.
3OFletcher, L. and Merrill, W., The Uruguayan Agricultural Sector:
Priorities for Government Policies, Investment Programs and Projects
(Washington, D.C., 1970).
3IMinisterio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Cuarto Proyecto de Desarrollo Ganadero de
Uruguay (Montevideo, 1971).
32Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, Quinto Proyecto de Desarrollo
Ganadero del Uruguay (Montevideo, 1974).
33International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Appraisal of
the Fifth Livestock Development Project Uruguay (Washington, D.C , 1976).
34Hunting Technical Services Limited, and Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Agricultural Diversification Study--Uruguay
(Montevideo, 1976).
35International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Appraisal of
Agricultural Diversification Project--Uruguay (Washington, D.C., 1976).
54
Quantitative studies of demands have been conducted in Argentina.
Beef production and consumption patterns in Argentina are similar to
those of Uruguay. Guadagni36 in 1964 estimated a demand relation for
beef with per capita beef consumption as a dependent variable. He used
price of beef, price of pork, price of lamb, per capita income, and
per capita consumptiop lagged QHEH¥SE:MEE.IPIEEEEQED¢ variables. He
found that the most significant variable affecting consumption was the
price of beef. Income was less important, and the price of beef sub-
stitutes was found to be even less significant. He concluded that
“the high consumption of beef in Argentina makes it inelastic to changes
in per capita income.“ He further concluded that in Argentina there
is a lack of true substitutes for beef.
Otrera37 estimated the domestic demand for beef where price of
beef was a function of total beef supply, total domestic consumption
of beef, time, per capita national income, and population. His
findings were similar to those of Guadagni. The price of beef was
the most important variable affecting domestic consumption.
Otrera included an export demand for beef in his model. He used
quantity of beef exported as the dependent variable and total beef
supply, internal price of beef, and the Argentinian population as
explanatory variables. Use of the internal beef price in the export
demand equation instead of the international or export price of beef
36Guadagni, A.A., ”Estudio Econometrico del Consumo de Carne Vacuna en
Argentina en el periodo 1914—1959" Desarrollo Economico 3 (1964).
37Otrera,Wylian R., "An Econometric Model for Analyzing Argentine Beef
Export Potentials” (Ph D. dissertation, Texas A&M University, 1966).
55
implies that the quantity of beef exported is the residual after
satisfying domestic consumption. No role is given to the international
price in determining the quantity of beef to be exported.
A contrasting point of view in the treatment of the export demand
for beef was presented by Nores.38 His study considered exports as
playing an active role in the mechanism of beef price formation at the
farm level. He proposed an export demand equation in which the inter—
national demand for Argentinian beef is a function of the price of Argen-
tinian beef, the price of beef offered by supply—competing countries,
the aggregate disposable income of beef-importing countries, and the
farmers' beef price in importing countries.
In the case of Uruguay there are no quantitative evaluations of
the international demand for Uruguayan meat. However, almost all
descriptive analyses recognize explicitly or implicitly that the amount
of beef available for exports will be the surplus above the traditional
level of domestic per capita consumption. The fourth and fifth Live-
stock Development Projects prepared by the government of Uruguay state
as their main objectives: ”To provide technical and credit assistance
to cattle producers to increase beef production. Increased beef pro-
duction will make available more beef for exports.”
In an evaluation report of the Livestock Development Project of
Uruguay conducted by the World Bank, a similar conclusionwasreached.39
38Nores, Gustavo A., ”An Econometric Model of the Argentine Beef-Cattle
Economy“ (Master's thesis, Purdue University, 1969).
39International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Uruguay Third
and Fourth Livestock Development Projects (Washington, D.C., 1976).
56
It concluded that due to the fact that the level of beef consumption in
Uruguay has always been a political issue in which the consumer has
been the winner, exports of beef will not increase unless beef produc-
tion is increased. This point of view, considering Uruguayan beef
exports a surplus over and above domestic consumption, is shared in
40’41 These studies appear to suggest for the Uruguayan
other studies.
beef export demand a similar model to the one used by Otrera in
Argentina.
Beef Demand Equations
Considering traditional economic theory and the findings of
previous studies conducted in Uruguay and Argentina, the following
specifications for the Uruguayan domestic and export beef demand are
proposed:
(1) BDIC = f(RPB, PC, PP, GNI, POP)
where:
BDIC = beef demand for internal consumption
RPB = retail price of beef
PC = price of chicken
PP = price of pork
GNI = gross national income
POP = population
(2) BDE = f(PCBC, TBS, POP)
4OComision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, E1 Plan Agropecuario (1972).
4IMinisterio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Lineamientos de Politica Agropecuaria
(Montevideo, 1972).
57
where:
BDE = beef demand for exports
PCBC = per capita beef consumption
TBS = total beef supply
POP = population
The total quantity of beef demanded is equal to the sum of the
demand for domestic consumption plus the demand for exports, or
(3) TBD = BDIC + BDE
The complete system consists of the following seven relationships:
four behavioral equations (number of beef cattle slaughtered, meat
yield per animal slaughtered, domestic demand for beef, and export
demand for beef); two identities (total beef supply=number of beef
cattle slaughtered times meat yield, and TBD = BDIC + BDE), and a
market clearing condition (total beef supply=tota1 beef demanded).
The Statistical Model
Economic theory suggests the directional effect that some variables
have upon others. Those effects were presented before when an economic
model with its behavioral relationships was postulated. A statistical
model to quantify the economic behavior of the variables affecting the
beef—cattle sector is presented here.
From a mathematical point of view, a linear functional relationship
between the variables is postulated. In general terms the linear
model can be considered as followsz4‘2’43
42Kelejan, H., Oates, W., Introduction to Econometrics, Principles and
Applications (New York: Harper & Row Publishers, 1974).
43Neter, J. and Wasserman, W., Applied Linear Statistical Models (Homewood,
Ill.: Richard 0. Irwin, Inc., 1974).
58
Yt =12] Bixit+Ut t = l n
where:
Yt = dependent or endogenous variable
it = independent or exogenous variables
Bi = coefficient or parameters of the independent variables,
indicating the effect of the independent variables on the
dependent variable
Ut = the random terms. They represent the effect of the
independent variable left out of the equation or the
measurement errors of the dependent variable.
For the purposes of this analysis, some assumptions related to
the variables and the error terms of the equations in the model are
made. All values of the independent variable should not be the same.
This enables us to observe the changes in the dependent variable
when Xt changes and therefore to estimate the parameters. Also, no
exact linear relationship is expected to exist among X Otherwise,
t'
a problem of multicollinearity will arise.
The expected value of the error term is assumed to be zero. The
error terms are assumed to be normally distributed. The variance of
the error term is constant (homoscedasticity). The previous assumption
characterized the error term as an unobservable random variable with
mean zero and constant variance and with the property that its value
in some instances is independent of its value in another instance and
then uncorrelated. Additionally, it is assumed that the error term
is independent of all the values of the regressor, which implies a zero
covariance with them (nonautoregression).
59
The specification of the relationship between the dependent and
independent variables plus the previous assumptions constitutes the
basic general statistical model. The equations that will be estimated
are particular cases of this model.
Equations and Variable Definitions
Due to the lack of statistical models for the Uruguayan beef
cattle economy, a very general and exploratory model is presented.
All variables that are believed to have some effect in each equation
(based on previous knowledge and studies in other countries) are in-
cluded and will be tried in the empirical analysis. At that time only
the equations including variables with greater explanatory power will
be included.
Eguations
Beef Supply
Number of beef cattle slaughtered.
l) NBCSt = f1(FBPt,FBPt1,PWt,PWt_],IPt,Pt_],IPCt,IPCt_1,CSt,CSt_1)
i=1. . . 5 i=l,3,4
Meat yield per animal slaughtered.
2) MYPASt = f2(IPCt,IPCt_],IP,IPt_],FBPt,SERAt)
Total beef supply identity.
3) TBSt = NBCSt x MYPASt
60
Beef Demand
Beef demand for international consumption.
4) BDICt = f3(FBPt,PCt,PPt,GNIt,POPt)
Beef demand for exports.
5) BDEt = f4(FBPt,TBSt,POPt)
Total beef demand identity.
6) TBDt = BDICt + BDE
Market clearing condition.
7) TBSt = TBDt
The variables used in the equations are defined below. The sym-
bols used were previously defined in this chapter.
Variable Definitions
Endogenous Variables
NBCSt = number of beef cattle slaughtered measured in thousand
head per year
MYPASt = average meat yield per animal slaughtered measured in
kilograms/animal of carcass weight equivalent
BDICt = quantity of beef demanded for internal consumption in
thousand tons of carcass weight equivalent
BDEt = quantity of beef demanded for exports in thousand tons of
carcass weight equivalent
Exogenous
FBPt
Pwt-l
IP
IPt-l
IPC
Ipct_1
SERAt
PC
PP
GNI
POP
61
Variables
farmers' beef prices in new Uruguayan pesos per ton divided
by the consumer price index
farmers' beef prices as previously defined, lagged different
numbers of years
farmers' wool prices in new Uruguayan pesos per 10 kilo-
grams, divided by the consumer price index
farmers' wool prices as previously defined, lagged one year
improved natural pastures in thousands of hectares in
production, each year
improved natural pastures, as previously defined, lagged
one year
index of pasture conditions, presented as an annual coefficient
of availability of roughage
index of pasture conditions, as previously defined, lagged
one year
slaughter extraction rate, percentage of total beef cattle
stock slaughtered each year.
price of chicken in new Uruguayan pesos per kilograms
divided by the consumer price index
price of pork in new Uruguayan pesos per ton divided by
the consumer price index
gross national income in millions of Uruguayan new pesos
divided by the consumer price index
Uruguayan population at June 20, in thousand inhabitants
62
An a priori specified sign for the coefficients of the variables
in the equations is proposed. The sign refers to the parameters of
the variables that are listed:
NBCS Equation FBPt
FBP >O, PWtO, IP >0, IPC <0,
t-5 1 t-1 t
IPC <0, CS >0, CS 0
t—l t t-1>
MYPAS Equation IPCt>O, IPCt_]>O, IPt>O, IPt_]>O, FBPt>O, SERAtO, PPt>O, GNI>O, POP>O
BDE Equation FBPt>O, TBSt>O, POPt 000000000
0000 000>-0>00V
00000: 000 0005000000 000000 00000 000 00oo0m
00000000000 000 0000000000002 000 000050000 000050000
_.m m0m<0
74
00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 30
00. 00. 00. 00. 0a
00.0 0.0000 00.0 c.0o0 . 00.0 0.0000 00.0 0.0000 00000000
00.0 0000. 00.0 00mm. 00.0 0000. 00.0 000m. 00
00.0 0000.1 00.0 0000.- 00.0 0000.1 00.0 0000.1 x000
0000.1 0000. 0000.1 0000.1 50m
00. 0000. 00.0 0000. 00. 0000. 00. 0000. 001000000
00. 0000. 00.0 0000. 0m. 0000. 00.0 0000. 001000000
00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 001000000
00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 00.0 0000. 001000000
00.0 0000.1 00. 0000.1 m0. 00_o.1 00.0 0000.1 001000000
00.0 0000.1 00.m 0000.1 00.0 0m00.1 00.0 0000.1 001000000
00000 .0 .00000 00000 .0 .00000 00000 .0 .00000 00000 .0 .00000
0000000>
000000 000 000000 000 000000 000 000000 000 00000000000
00000000000 000000000000:
0000000000m 000000 000m 00 000502 ”0000000> 000000000
0000 000>1x0mv
00000: 000 0005000000 000000 00000 000 00oo0m
00000000000 000 0000000000000 000 000050000 000050000
0.m m0m<0
75
These values indicate inconclusive tests for autocorrelation; in other
words,the hypothesis of no autocorrelation has to be rejected. The
value and high statistical significance of the parameters not included
in the lag structure are another reason for the selection of this
equation.
The estimated equation for the number of beef cattle slaughtered
follows. Below the estimated parameters, their respective standard
errors appear in parentheses. Parameters which are more than twice
their standard error are indicated with a double asterisk. One
asterisk indicates parameters which are larger than their error terms.
The Durbin—Watson statistic test for autocorrelation is represented by
the letter d. The computed d value has an a attached if the hypothesis
of no autocorrelation has to be rejected in favor of the alternative
hypothesis of autocorrelated disturbance terms. The letter i indicates
an inconclusive test, and the letter n indicates the nonrejection of
the hypothesis of no autocorrelated disturbance terms at the 5 percent
level of significance.
(1) most = 805.97l-0.2577**FBPR(
—0.0398 FBPR( +O.l08l*FBPR(
t—l) t—2)
(368.7ll) (0.0756) (0.0583) (0.0594)
t-3)
** ** *‘k *
+ 0.l86l FBPR( +O.l940 FBPR( +0.1320 FBPR( -0.5802 IPCXt
t-4) t-5) t-6)
(0.0609) (0.0533) (0.0334) (0.3089)
**
+ 0.3338 IPt
(0.0937)
'fi2 = 0.77 d = 2.33(n)
where:
FBPR
farmers' beef price deflated by the consumer price index
IPCX
ll
first difference for the index of pasture conditions
IP total number of hectares of improved pasture in production
76
The effect of beef prices on the number of beef cattle supplied
for slaughter is negative for two years and positive thereafter. The
total magnitude of the effect of price on number of cattle slaughtered
is expressed in terms of the price-slaughter supply elasticities.
The short—run price elasticity of slaughter is -0.26, and the
long-run elasticity is 0.32 (see Table 5.3). The results presented
in the table indicate that if the price of beef increases (decreases)
by l0 percent, beef cattle slaughtered will decrease (increase) by
2.6 percent in the following year. It will take, with the production
conditions prevailing in Uruguay, four years to regain the level of
slaughter supply existing at the moment of the price increase. After
six years, the total number of beef cattle slaughtered will be in—
creased (decreased) by 3.2 percent.
TABLE 5.3
Simple and Cumulative Price Elasticities
of Total Slaughter
Time Dependent Variable FBPR FBPR
Period Simple Elasticity Cumulative Elasticity
t-l -O.26 —O.26
t-2 -0.04 -O.3O
t-3 0.ll -O.l9
t-4 0.l9 0.00
t-5 0.l9 0.l9
t-6 0.l3 0.32
77
Capital investment in any industry is generally a positively
sloped function of the market price of the product that the industry
produces. The cattle industry presents a unique characteristic when
compared with most other industries. Its product is both a consumption
and an investment good. When the price of beef increases, we would
expect the capital stock to increase. The farmers make the capital
stock investment withholding animals from slaughter in order to increase
future production, which implies a short-run supply of animals for
slaughter with a negative price elasticity. In the long run, however,
as production increases, supply of cattle for slaughter also becomes
higher than previous levels. The long-run supply of cattle will then
present, in contrast with the short-run supply, a positive price elas-
ticity. However, most previous studies have found both short and long-
run negative price supply elasticities of cattle for slaughter.
Jarvis1 estimated an equation to explain the number of beef
cattle slaughtered in Uruguay each year between l960 and l977. He
lagged the price of beef one year, but other lag periods were not
included. The estimated short-run price elasticity of slaughter
(year t-l) was —O.30l. Table 5.4 shows that the short-run price elas-
ticity of slaughter estimated by Jarvis in Uruguay is very similar to
the one estimated in this study. No other similar studies have been
done in Uruguay; nevertheless, there are various Argentinian studies
on cattle-supply response to beef prices.
1Jarvis, Lowell S., "The Economic Determinants of Uruguayan Beef-Cattle
Herd and Slaughter Levels, l960—l976” (Unpublished paper, Montevideo,
l977).
78
TABLE 5.4
Short and Long-Run Price Elasticities of
Slaughter Estimated in Previous Studies
Elasticity
Author Country Study Period Short-Run Long-Run
Jarvis Uruguay l960-76 — 0.30 n.e.a
Reca Argentina l923-47 n.e. - 0.36
Nores Argentina l935-66 0.003 - 0.3l4
Iver Argentina l937-67 - 0.l6 l.l4
Otrera Argentina l945-64 - 2.48 - 2.66
Reca Argentina l948-65 n.e. - 0.2l
This Study Uruguay l956-75 - 0.26 0.32
an.e. = not estimated.
The main discrepancy between this study and those done by Reca,2
Nores,3 and Otrera4 in Argentina lies in their findings of a negative
long-run price elasticity of slaughter. These Argentinian studies
imply a behavior of the cattle industry which is inconsistent with the
observed Uruguayan situation. In Uruguay,5 Argentina,6 and other
2Reca, Lucio G., "The Price and Production Duality Within Argentine
Agriculture l923-l965” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago, l967).
3Nores, Gustavo A., "An Econometric Model of the Argentine Beef-Cattle
Economy” (Master's thesis, Purdue University, l969).
4Otrera, Wylian R., "An Econometric Model for Analyzing Argentine Beef
Export Potentials” (Ph.D. dissertation, Texas A&M University, l966).
5Secco, Garcia J. and Perez, Arrarte C., ”El Ciclo Ganadero," Revista
de la Asociacion de Ingenieros Agronomos (Montevideo, l975).
6Iver, Raul E., "The Investment Behavior and the Supply Response of the
Cattle Industry in Argentina" (Ph.D. dissertation, University of
Chicago, l97l).
79
countries,7 it has been indicated that cattle firms actually behave
following economic investment theory. When the price of beef increases,
the farmers increase their capital stock (reducing the number of cattle
supplied for slaughter). Once the investment in capital stock results
in increased production (a process that can take between 3 to 6 years
depending on the production technology), the number of cattle supplied
for slaughter exceeds the level of supply existing before the price
increase. This result implies a positive long-run supply elasticity
of slaughter.
Iver used a polynomial distributed lag model in which the farmers'
beef price was lagged for five years. The positive long—run supply
elasticity of slaughter is much greater than the elasticity estimated
for this study (Table 5.4). Some of the factors which can account for
the discrepancy include the fact that Argentina's cattle production is
similar to Uruguay's cattle production, but still some differences
remain. Second, length of run of the distributed lag structures is
different. Third, a single equation technique is used in this study
to estimate the number of beef cattle slaughtered,whereas Iver used a
simultaneous equation approach to estimate the system of equationsin
which he disaggregated beef-cattle slaughter.
Meat Yield Per Animal Slaughtered
Several variables were postulated as affecting the meat yield per
animal slaughtered. The farmers' price of beef, the number of hectares
7Kalaitzis, Vassilios C., "An Econometric Analysis of the Feed-Grain
Livestock Economy of Greece” (Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State
University, l978).
80
of improved pastures in production, the cattle stock, the index of pas-
ture conditions,and the slaughter extraction rate were among the explana-
tory variables that were tried in different combinations and forms of
expression. The resulting equation for meat yield per animal slaughtered
is:
* 'k
(2) MYPASt = 230.530+O.4507 *IPCXt-O.l845 *SERAt
(5.799) (0.0745) (0.035l)
where:
IPCX = index of pasture conditions
SERA = slaughter extraction rate
R2 = 0.86 d = l.68(n)
Higher values of the index of pasture conditions indicate more
availability of roughage. As more roughage is available, the average
meat yield per animal slaughtered increases. This is explained by the
fact that in Uruguay, raising and fattening of cattle is done by direct
grazing. No practice of forage reserves is followed, and all the
potential livestock areas are already in use. The introduction of
improved pastures has helped to reduce seasonal fluctuations, but
they still represent a small percentage of the total grazing area
(ll percent). Given this situation, the climatic conditions play an
important role in determining forage supply and therefore in the yield
that fattening animals can reach.
The slaughter extraction rate (SERA) is defined as the total num-
ber of animals slaughtered divided by the total number of animals in
stock. This variable is also related to the problem of lack of adequate
quantity of roughage. In the case of Uruguay in most years, the extrac-
tion rate is an indication of the percentage of animals that had to
8]
be sold before being finished due to a lack of forage rather than to
an index of high productivity. This explains the negative relation-
ship between SERA and the meat yield per animal slaughtered.
In Argentina, Otrera and Nores found that the climatic conditions
significantly affect the yield per animal slaughtered. The slaughter
extraction rate was not included in their equations.
The Derived Demand for Roughage
Since practically no silage or hay is produced in Uruguay, the
derived demand for additional roughage is referred to as the demand
for inputs to improve the country's natural pasture. This demand is
measured in terms of the annual gross investment in improved pastures
expressed in hectares.
The farmers' beef price, the price of phosphate fertilizer (the
fertilizer used for improving pastures), and the interest rate were
used for this equation. The chosen estimated equation is:
AGIIPt = l48.000+0.2664**FBPRFt—l8.52l3**IRRt
(40.736) (0.l094) (3.3470)
where:
FBPRF= farmers' beef price/price of phosphate fertilizer
IRR = real rate of interest
R2 = 0.80 d = 1.92(”)
The annual gross investment in improved pastures as measured in number
of hectares improved(AGIIPt)is significantly affected by the price of
beef, the price of phosphate fertilizer, and the real rate of interest.
82
When the relationship farmer beef prices/price of phosphate fer-
tilizer, both deflated GBPRF),increases, so does the investment in pasture
improvement. No Uruguayan study has quantified this relationship, but
different documents indicate this positive relationship. The relation—
ship farmer beef prices/price of phosphate fertilizer has varied since
l96l between l.6 and 3.6. Higher values of this relationship coincide
with a higher number of hectares of pastures improved.8’9’]0
The parameter estimate for the real rate of interest has an impor-
tant and highly significant effect statistically on the explained
variable AGIIP. Between l96l and l968, the nominal rate of interest
on loans for pasture improvements varied between ll and 26 percent.
In the same period, Uruguay had a high annual rate of inflation. With
only the exception of l968, the inflation rate has been higher than 50
percent. This resulted in a negative interest rate, especially when
it is considered that the loans had two years'grace period for the
principal and five years to be repaid. In 1969 an indexing system was
introduced, but the way in which it was applied and the indicators that
it had as a base determined that the interest rate still continued to
be negative for most of the years. According to a World Bank study,
the imperfect indexing system applied since I969 has still resulted in
8Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Cuarto Proyecto de Desarrollo Ganadero
(Montevideo, l97l).
9Comision Honoraria del Plan Agropecuario, Quinto Proyecto de Desarrollo
Ganadero del Uruguay (Montevideo, l974).
10Ministerio de Agricultura y Pesca, Conclave l977 (Montevideo, l977).
83
an average negative interest rate of approximately l0 percent.H
Since the controlled price of beef has not been an incentive for
investment in the livestock sector, it appears that the negative rate
of interest on loans offered by the government for improved pastures
technology has taken that investment incentive role. The effect of
these loans has been important in the introduction of this technology
if it is considered that,first, 98 percent of the producers who invested
in improved pastures received government loans, and, second, that
practically no other source of credit either from the government or
from the private sector existed for investment in the livestock sector.
Subsidies for phosphate fertilizer have also existed in most
years. The role of the fertilizer subsidy for investment has been
similar to that of the credit subsidy. That is, when the subsidy for
phosphate fertilizer was reduced, it had an effect that was similar to
that of reducing the price of beef. When the interest rate due to
varying inflation became less negative, it had a similar effect to
that of reduced beef prices.
Testing the Supply Equations
One of the important uses of the estimated equations is to fore-
cast what change can be expected to occur in the dependent variable
in terms of direction and magnitude, when the value of one or more of
the independent variables varies. This is particularly important in
the case of Uruguay where some of these variables are government
HInternational Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Uru uay Third
and Fourth Livestock Development Projects (Washington, D.C., l976).
84
controlled. 0n the other hand, the traditional view of government
policies in Uruguay toward the fact that beef exports are the residual,
after internal consumption has been satisfied, puts the emphasis on
increasing beef production if a higher level of exports is to be
achieved. The evaluation of the forecasting ability of the supply
model is achieved using a graphical technique and Theil's U-coefficient
of inequality.12
A desirable feature of the model is its ability to predict turning
points in the event or variable that is under study. Four possibilities
can be identified with respect to prediction of turning points:
(i) correct prediction of a turning point, i.e., a predicted turning
point actually occurring; (ii) incorrect prediction of a turning
point, i.e., a turning point is predicted when there is no actual
turning point; (iii) a turning point is not predicted, but an actual
turning point does exist; and (iv) correct no prediction of a turning
point, i.e., a turning point is not predicted when a turning point does
not exist.
Cases (ii) and (iii) represent failure in prediction of turning
points, and they are described as Type I failure (Q1) and Type II
failure (02) respectively.
Q1 (ii) 02 - (iii)
W (1 +(iii
12Theil, H., Economic Forecast and Policy (Amsterdam: North Holland
Publishing Company, l965).
85
01 represents the set of predicted turning points that contains no
actual turning points. 02 represents the set of actual turning points
that contain no predicted ones. These are quantitative measures of
the failure to forecast a turning point with the following value range
05010251. If any of the predicted turning points coincide with the
actual points 01 and 02=l, then small values of Q1 and 02 indicate the
presence of a successful turning point.
The values of Q1 and 02 are small for the estimated supply equa-
tions. In particular,a perfect turning point forecasting is achieved
in the identity equation explaining total beef supply (see Table 5.5).
The graphical analysis is based on the actual and predicted values of
the supply equation as presented in Figure55.l, 5.2, 5.3, and 5.4.
TABLE 5.5
Ability to Forecast Turning Points
Supply Equations
(Quantitative Measure of Graphical
Analysis for Supply Equations)
Variables Actual Predicted
Turning Point N0 Turning Point 01 02
NBCS Turning Point (i)=5 (iii)=l
No Turning Point (ii)=l (iu)=5 0.l7 0.l7
MYPAS Turning Point (i)=8 (iii)=l
No Turning Point (ii)=l (iu)=4 0.ll 0.ll
TBS Turning Point (i)=7 (iii)=0
No Turning Point (ii)=0 (iu)=5 0.00 0.00
AGIIP Turning Point (i)=2 (iii)=l
N0 Turning Point (ii)=l (iu)=8 0.33 0.33
86
.uwgwpcmszm mFPHmu comm mo LwaE:z
on
P
as:
me
we
mw=_m> cmumewumm
mw:_m> Fmapu<
._.m aczaca
o—_
cONF
oom_
8:
9; _
some
ooNF
comp
.82
SDSN
87
:8? ma_ 2a,
_»m_
.eacau;m=a_m _mec:< 28a e_aw> paw:
Ofia_
ama_
mace
mam—
Ama_
owm_
momp
.N.m aczmca
vom— mom—
Nom—
mw:_m> vmpmswumm
mm:_m> _m=po<
owr
wa
Lb
on
,_
v
OFN
mrm
SVdAW
(qualeAInbg $523423 sweafioltx)
88
TBS (000 MT)
370‘ ._______.———.Actual Values
----— - -- Estimated Values
360,
350_
340_
330.
A
I
I \
320. 1’ \i
I \
/ \
/ \
310, / ‘
I ‘ I
I ‘ I
h I ‘ I
300, I “~. I ‘ I
/ '1 I ‘ I
’ \ I ‘ '
X \ I ‘ ’
290‘ / \ I i
l/ \ I \
\ ' ‘
l ’ ‘
280 I ‘
4 l ‘
‘ I \
I \
\ I \\
270 \ I ‘
i \ I \
\ I ‘v
\ I
260 l ’
-4 ‘ I]
\ I
250i ‘ I,
K\ I
\
\
\
240.
230 . ‘ .T , , , . . .
1963 64 65 66 67
68 69 70 7l 72 73 74 75
Time
Figure 5.3. Total Beef Supplied.
89
.moczpmmm vw>ocaEH cw “cospmm>cH mmocw Fmscc< .v.m mgzmwu
2.:
mm «m mu mm —m om mm mm
mo:_m> umumswumm IIIIIII
mw:_m> —m:uo<
om
ron:
vom—
com
‘omm
com
.fi mmm
dIIBV
)
(saaeqoaH 000
90
The Theil's coefficient of inequality or U coefficient is used
here to measure the ability of the model to forecast the course of the
future supply of beef in the cattle industry. The Theil's U coefficient
is calculated as follows:
u l/n 22:] (Pt - At)2
l/n 22:] PE + l/n 22:] A:
where:
Pt = predicted value of the th observation for t=(l . . . .n)
At = actual value of the th observation for t=(l . . . .n)
When all predicted values of P are equal to all actual values of
t
A U=0, we have total equality or a perfect forecast. The opposite
t’
case occurs when we have maximum of inequality; then U=l. In this
latter case no worthwhile forecast can be made since the model is not
able to accurately predict the past. Between 0 and l, the closer
the U coefficient is to zero the better the forecasting ability of the
model.
In our case the U coefficients are very close to zero, which
supports the contention that the model's forecasting accuracy should
not be suspect (Table 5.6).
TABLE 5.6
Theil's U Coefficient of Inequality for the Supply Equations
Variable Variable Name Coefficient
NBCS Number of Beef Cattle Slaughtered 0.0323
MYPAS Meat Yield Per Animal Slaughtered 0.007l
TBS Total Beef Supply 0.0373
AGIIP Annual Gross Investment Improved 0.ll92
Pastures
91
Beef Supply Forecasting
Most of the factors affecting the supply of beef are controlled by
the government. Of these variables, the most important factor is the
farmers' beef price. This price has been traditionally low (according
to the international price level) to protect urban consumers. Different
assumptions are made with respect to alternative government beef price
policies. Each alternative is evaluated in terms of the supply of
beef that would result: Alternative l: increase of 25 percent in the
price of beef; Alternative 2: increase of 50 percent; and Alternative
3: increase of the price of beef to the export or international beef
price. (Once the price is increased it is assumed to remain at that
level throughout the forecast period.) Alternative 3, which represents
the highest price increase, is equivalent to letting the market set
the price. It is also assumed that an infinite quantity of Uruguayan
beef could be sold in the international market.
The increase of the price of beef will directly affect the supply
of cattle for slaughter first through the herd buildup (reduction of
supply), later through an increase in the supply (after the third
year), and indirectly through the effect on investment in improved
pastures. The number of improved pastures in production affects the
total cattle supply for slaughter.
Assuming all other factors constant, the direct and indirect
effects of an increase in the price of beef will result in a net
increase in the total quantity of beef supplied after a four-year
period. If Alternative l is followed, the quantity of beef supplied
will increase in a period of six years by 7.0 percent, 25,800 tons of
carcass weight equivalent. If Alternative 2 is chosen, the increase
92
will amount to l4.l percent or 51,800 tons. Alternative 3 will yield
an increase of 104,000 tons of beef supplied. The importance of this
increase in supply is that all of the increased quantities would be
exported. Actually, when the price of beef increases, local consump-
tion will decrease making even larger the amount of beef available
for exports. It is important to notice, though, that higher production
increases require higher investment in capital stock. This would
further imply a greater reduction in beef supply during the first two
or three years (see Table 5.7). The forecast was made for a six-year
period starting in l976 since no actual data were yet available for
beef supply in l977 and l978. Nevertheless, the direction and magnitude
of the forecast change is not affected from a practical point of view
if those two years had been available and the forecast were extended
to 1984.
TABLE 5.7
Forecast of Beef Supplied Under Different Assumptions of
Beef Price Increases and of Interest Rate (000 M.T.)a
Increases in Beef Prices To Export Price and
Years 25%b 50%b To Export Priceb % Real Interest Rate
l976 367.0 367.0 367.0 367.0
l977 345.8 324.4 28l.8 27l.8
l978 34l.7 3l5.4 266.2 255.3
l979 353.9 340.6 3l4.6 304.4
l980 372.9 378.5 396.2 380.l
l98l 386.4 405.5 444.2 434.2
l982 392.8 4l8.8 47l.0 46l.0
aThousandsof metric tons.
bSubsidized interest rate of loans for improved pastures.
93
Other factors such as the price of phosphate fertilizer and the
interest rate on loans for establishing improved pastures, also con-
trolled by the government, affect the total supply of beef. Both
factors have been traditionally highly subsidized. In the previous
estimation of the yield of different courses of action in relation to
the beef price, the market price (without subsidy) of phosphate fer—
tilizers was used. The interest rate used was the subsidized one.
If the price of beef is allowed to reach the level of the inter-
national market (at FOB Montevideo prices), the price of phosphate
fertilizer is the ongoing market price,and the interest rate reaching
real terms is assumed to be 8 percent. The beef supply will then
increase 26 percent over a period of six years (see Table 5.7 and
Figure 5.5). The previous assumptions are very close to those that
the free market mechanism will set for prices of product and inputs
that affect the supply of beef in Uruguay. The magnitude in the change
of the value of the exogenous variables that these assumptions imply
is significant, for the farmers' beef price represents doubling its
l975 level. A similar change will result from the interest rate,
which would increase by almost two and a half times its l975 level.
Price of fertilizer would remain at the market price of l975.
The market mechanism would allow the increase in exports by some
94,000 tons of beef per year during a six-year period. At l975 prices
this increase would represent an additional income for the country of
l06 million U.S. dollars. The total dollar figure for all Uruguayan
exports was 385 million for l975 and was estimated to be around 600
million for l977.
Nm
—
.Amcou o_prE Ucmm305p :wv argazm wmwm quOH ammowLOm ucm Fmauo< .m.m wL:m_d
meme
Fm ow mm mm mm ox mm «A MR Nu FR Om me me No we me we moor
s . . > . .
. . . ooa
0mm
.oov
omv
N3 IIIIIIII
90m l ..... 1|.II
omv
mo_cm “Loaxm 0H
mcowuoazmm<
mmmmcocfi mowca comm
(IN 000) $81
95
The Estimated Demand Equations
Two demand equations and one identity determine total demand in
this study. The two estimated equations are: (l) beef demand for
internal consumption, and (2) beef demand for exports. The identity
that determines total demand is the product of both equations.
Beef Demand for Internal Consumption
Several factors are implied in economic theory and in previous
studies for other countries as affecting the demand for beef. In par—
ticular, the retail price of beef, the price of beef substitutes in
consumption, and the level of income per capita are considered deter-
minants of the demand for beef.
Previous descriptive studies and the author's knowledge of the
beef—cattle industry of Uruguay indicate that from a practical point
of view no beef substitutes in consumption exist in Uruguay. At the
same time, many have contended that the income level has not significantly
affected beef consumption. This argument is based on the fact that the
government, for political reasons, has always made beef readily avail—
able to the Uruguayan population, which enjoys one of the highest
levels of beef consumption in the world. Despite the fact that the
previous statement appears in all the literature on the subject, a
quantification has not been established. For this reason, different
equations were tried including all variables that, at least from a
theoretical point of view, affect the consumption of beef.
Beef demand for internal consumption is expressed in terms of the
per capita beef consumption in kilograms. The prices of beef, pork,
chicken, and fish in Uruguayan pesos are deflated by the consumer price
96
index. The level of income is in per capita terms and is also deflated
by the consumer price index. The quantity of beef exported is also
investigated as an explanatory variable.
The only parameter found to have a statistically significant
effect on beef consumption is the parameter for the retail price of
beef. The price of beef substitutes, per capita income, and the quan-
tity of beef exported were not statistically significant in any of the
equations, and some of them appear with the wrong expected sign (see
Table 5.8). This result appears to confirm the arguments presented in
various descriptive studies of the Uruguayan beef sector.
All the equations have a very low R2. This is probably due to
the failure to represent all the forms of government intervention taken
to protect the urban consumer. Implicitly or explicitly, the govern-
ment's target has always been to assure a high level of domestic beef
13 the
consumption. In the national development plan for 1973-77,
government set as an explicit target to reduce domestic consumption
from the historical average of around 75 kilograms (l65.4 pounds) to
65 kilograms (143.3 pounds) per capita per annum. The reason was to
increase the amount of beef exported. The target was not achieved.14
Since 1974, the beef consumption has been over 80 kilograms (176.4
pounds) per capita per year. No government appears to have been able
13Ministerio de Ganaderia y Agricultura, Oficina de Programacion y
Politica Agropecuaria, Lineamientos de Politica Agropecuaria
(Montevideo, 1973).
14Ministerio de Agricultura y Pesca, Conclave l977 (Montevideo, 1977).
97
xcoa mo mowga n ma;
:mx8wco no mo_ga n mum
uwugoqxw wmmn we zuwucmzc u xmmo
gm.c co aocca n ma;
mEoucw muvgmo Log n Hum
memo we wowga _wmpoc u mmam
.xmucr woven Lossmcou An cops—wow wEoucw ccc mmowcu —_<
Acvmo.m e¢.o u Amoao.ov AmN.av a
mmamxtkmn_.o - waa._a ” Qmua Amv
A5m: _e.o p Aammo.ov p Ammem.ov a Ammmo.ov Aam.wv a
xmmo mm_o.o - mHoa NA8_.O + «mamawmke_.o - .aem.om u umua Aev
Aevmm.fi 44.0 a AFNN_.QV a Amom.ov a A_mmo.ov Amq.mv a
mag mm~_.o + mfiua wpm.o - «mamwkmaw_.o - waaa.om n umua Amy
Acvmw._ m¢.o u Amemm.ov p ANFm.ov a Acma.ov a flammo.ov Aom.mv 8
«am m8m_.o + «ca amo.o + «Hum aom.o - mmax.4NmAF.o - 44mm.am u umua Amy
B Ammm.mv u Akmmo.ov a Aemkm.ov a Aomam.ov p Amom._v p Aommo.ov Amm.mv a
Avaw.F 8¢.o muaumom.o + xumo Ao_o.o - mam FNoN.o + maa_kmo.o + mHua mmm.o - mmamtamem_.o - stow.ow u umua A_v
a_aacta>
v mm mmpnmwcm> ucmwcmamvcH pcmEaawo
mcowpmzcm ucmsma wmmm owpmwsoo
m.m m4mw:cm Hgmwmz mmmocmum
.oxmsmzcs
meowpuEmgmz mo—mvoz ..Fm pm _mp:mswa ”mcowawucoo mczammm we xmvcH
owcmzuw o; < Louuwm pm new
.ovgmzowaoem< :MFQ use mmpcmm>oswm we Fm:o_omz cowuumcmo n>_aa:m wwmm ucm cmunmzm—m
.ommF vcm .oom_ .FomF .omm_ mowcmzomgocmoswm ww _m:owomz :ovoomgwo nm—upmu mo xuoum ”mocaom
nnw._ om_.F m.mcm m.wom m.o— o.mmm._ o.mom.__ mum”
Ame.” Noo.F m.nom o._om m.¢_ o.mmm.~ o._mm.o_ «NmF
NmN._ noo._ n.~c~ o.mON m.m_ o.oom._ N.oom.m mum”
man._ oFo._ m.o- o.mom o.<_ o.~om._ m.mm~.m N~o_
mom.p mvo.— _.mmm m.Nm_ o.w— o.om¢.F o.mNN.m _Nm_
mem._ mFo._ 0.0mm m.mm_ m._~ o._~w._ “.moo.w onF
Amo.— mko._ _.m_m m.mom N.w_ o.wmm._ o.Foo.m mom—
mmm.F Nma.o o.m~m o.mm_ m.w_ o.omm._ o.~mo.w moa—
mom.~ owm.o m.omm m.mom ¢.m_ o._m_._ 0.0Nm.w Nom—
eoo.— Nmo._ o.wm~ o.m_m m.m_ o.~o_._ N.nw_.w mmm_
m_v.— mma.o N.Nam m.~w_ m.m_ o.< cmucmszm «emu; :m_m mxoOpm mpupmu
x_aazm wmmm _mp0H use .pgmwmz mmmcw>< .gmugmsmfim .xooum mFQumu
< m4mwscm ucmwmz mmmocmum
.mow_nsamm m_ on cauwmcm>wcs
.mwowmmm meowum_umpmm Amsmscz umEoocH chovpmz mmocu Ucm cowpm_=aom cmxmamscz
.mwcmzowgoem< mowpw_om A cowomEmLmoca mu acwowwo ”cowpaazmcoo chcwucH ”mwogzom
116
N.NNN.N m.mw o.qmm.m m.omm mNmF
m.om¢.¢ m.om m.m¢m.m m.o—N amm—
m.nmm.m m.mm _.mmm.N o.wn_ mmm_
N.mmm._ m.mo w.o~m.m w.NNF Nmm_
“.mmm N.mm m.oom.~ _.mm_ _mm_
N.Npo o.w~ m.mmm.~ o.F_N enm—
_.oom m.Nw w.w~o.~ o._mm mmm_
m.vnm o.mw ¢.¢mm.m m.oww w©m_
w.mo_ m.ok m.0mo.N m.ow_ mom—
m.mm m.mm o.mmc.m o.vw_ mom_
m.mm o.—w m.NNo.N ¢.N_N mom_
m.mm o.mo _.mom.w v.on_ amm—
¢.mm w.v~ m.mmm.m F.vm_ mom—
w.w_ w.o~ m.mmm.m N.Pw_ Nmm_
m.m_ w.ow N.Nmm.m m.mom _mm—
m.m_ m.mm N.¢wv.m m.mm_ oom—
m.w m.m~ o.m¢v.m N.¢m~ amm—
o.© m.wm m.q_¢.m m.om— mmm_
_.m m._n v._mm.m m.ox— “mm—
m.m N.mw ©.wvm.m m.om_ 0mm—
AWL: mo mcow__wz mo_P¥ Hz coo
mEoocH v :owua%smcouvwmmm :oAchMMangcw mmov mcwwua23mwou me>
chowumz mmocu muwamu cm; wp _ a co w :L: Facewch
cowpassmcou wmwm chgwch
m MJmeceaw use Lew snow :e “mecmecu Am
.ewxmeeeeecm< :e—m wee aweccece: :ewmwsee Av
.
wecwEez we mews; .meescmm .mLeELen emcwzexm ugeexm
meczpmma we pcese>eeaEH Lew memee :e mama pmecwucH use .LerwwuLwd mumsemega
we mowce .Poez we mowca .wewca wmem .mLeELmd .wuea «meagexm .wewm we mewce ucequ
u m4m meewm> meewe> meawm> meewe> mezpe>
capeswpme Pazpo< empegwpmm ~8366< empaawpmm _a=pa<
88 :3 3:23.53 2363 3828 £285: 98: 88 8...;
.233 weem F38 eegepgmemwm Egg Len. 2e; pee: 8.829.um e—pueuweem Leesez
m.m 6:8 .N.m ._.m maezawa cw cam: 886D
n_ HES.
121
TABLE G
Data Used in Figure 5.4
Annual Gross Investment in
Improved Pastures
Year
Actual ' Estimated
Values Values
1961 18.0 10.2
1962 24.0 33.7
1963 32.0 14.5
1964 68.0 68.9
1965 91.0 164.4
1966 130.0 160.4
1967 145.0 176.2
1968 225.0 186.2
1969 200.0 186.2
1970 160.0 217.9
1971 270.0 265.2
1972 320.0 271.7
1973 308.0 280.7
1974 282.0 195.2
1975 110.0 180.6
122
“sesame>sw sew msmew se pmesepsw we ewes wees pseesee m
sw pseseme>sw sew msme— se mums umesepsw eerewmeem
esp .ewmw op meew>ese meme» esp see
.m.m esemws sew
use serwwpsew mpesemese sew mewse uexsez
.mesepmme ee>eseew sw
use serwwpsew epesemese sew mewse pexsezo
.meszpmee se>esesw
e
.eem: ewe: < e—eew we meme weepem
same we sew: esez mssewee.eessp pmsww eswm
o._ee o.wse e.w_e w.Nmm Nem_
N.eme N.eee m.moe 4.8em _mm_
_.omm N.mmm m.wsm m.~sm oea.
4.40m e.e_m e.eam m.mmm awm_
m.mm~ N.eem e.mpm A._em ewe,
m.FAN e._mN 8.6Nm m.mam snm_
o.~em c.58m o.~em o.wem osm—
awWWM mmommw oe aawsa psoaxm Op see we nemm we
.5 .. imam... a was. seamen...
sw emeesesH . . .
Aooo wzv
sepem pmeseusw use .msewwwwpses .weem we meewss
sew msewpe22mm< mews; usesewwwa sees: xwesem weem wmeew we emceeses
I m4m