The G" This is to certify that the thesis entitled AN INFORMATION SYSTEMS ANALYSIS OF USDA FARM INCOME DATA presented by Charles Henry Riemenschneider has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph-D- degree in Agnimliuxal Economics Mid, / (4%44/44/ Major professor Date OCtOber 30, 1978 0-7 639 OVERDUE FINES ARE 25¢ PER DAY _ PER ITEM w Return to book drop ‘to remove a this chemfrom your record. MIU . $6223 "5 AN INFORMATION SYSTEMS ANALYSIS OF USDA FARM INCOME DATA By Charles Henry Riemenschneider AN ABSTRACT OF A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1978 ABSTRACT AN INFORMATION SYSTEMS ANALYSIS OF USDA FARM INCOME DATA By Charles Henry Riemenschneider Problems relating to the data base in agriculture have been of concern in the agricultural economics profession in recent years. U.S. Department of Agriculture aggregate farm income data have been the sub- ject of a number of studies during this time. The failure of these studies to consider explicitly the ultimate data users as key variables in the analysis of farm income data has often led to an incorrect defi- nition of the nature of data system problems and has made it difficult to establish meaningful priorities among the recommendations of these earlier studies. This research is based on an information systems paradigm which emphasizes the use of information in decision making. A mail survey and personal interviews with farm income data users were the main research methods used. These yielded results which provided a description of the farm income information system and helped to define the nature of the problems in the system. The theoretical basis for the research was further expanded by developing the economic implications of the information systems paradigm. Emphasis in the theoretical area was on economic structure and the dis- tributions of information and income in determining the appropriate sir-ix Charles Henry Riemenschneider government role in supplying information. The farm income information system was found to have four major components, a primary data subsystem, a formatting and communication sub- system, an analysis subsystem and a decision making subsystem. Public policy uses of the farm income data dominated in the system. Major pri- vate sector uses were in the areas of estimating the demand for farm in- puts and for credit decisions relating to agriculture. The lack of use by many of those receiving the data or the low weight often attached to the farm income data in policy decisions was also a significant finding. The descriptive results pinpointed a number of problems in the farm income information system. Two major problem areas were identified by users. First, conceptual obsolescence is a major problem in the sys- tem. Through time the issues in agricultural policy have changed but the concepts of farm income have not. The current system fails to pro- vide adequate information on the distribution of farm income, especially by commodity and by legal organization, which are needed to address cur- rent policy issues. Conceptual obsolescence of a different type is also apparent because the national family farm data concept currently used is not a true representation of the reality of the farm sector. This lat- ter type of conceptual obsolescence does not appear as serious as the first since aggregate farm income data are used more as social indica- tors and thus do not require a one to one relationship with reality. Credibility is a second major problem area. Data revisions through time have tended to create a credibility problem for the USDA, especially with regard to analysis of farm income related issues in the policy pro- cess. Other minor issues were also addressed. These included the Charles Henry Riemenschneider i'ttjon of USDA farm income data into the national income and product éll"qnnts, the usefulness of the information systems paradigm as a re- 3.:stlrch methodology, the political sensitivity of data and the ability to hi Aiake changes in ongoing public data series. J 0 ..{p The major recommendations for improving the farm income informa- fv .. ' 'ijtton system were to improve data on the distribution of income, to make ;;iore use of directly reported data on production expenditures, to give . flower priorities to earlier suggestions that farm income data be pre- n.~ ' “l-sented in national income and product accounting formats, and to expand 57' 1the farm sector performance measures emphasized to improve the credibili- .1 .,‘ I :.' ty of the existing data and analysis done by the USDA. .51". - “'4 I. -- _‘~I ~ I. J we ' . -. ‘. ’ ,1. HJ' LI} .— t- * .7 x . _. x .. I_- .n ‘ {big rda few if. I; ,_ . ' . : ’ tog this n , r . . y. 14‘»... “m. Chairman cf » , , . _ l ,. _.. ., Kunm' mil. Adlai. .. . ‘- 1 122m: we “I ECODIJ‘I. l .;1.1' ‘r .i‘i“:"u€; ,lor.Deput,viavI~r-Iw _ - I. , 5‘ .. _. for. inrov‘ma‘m; . ' > ., ~ r . . '-'.I. mm. «on- t ”In the furic; IA; ‘. . , ‘ , ’ ' w ". . - I “‘3‘; ’i’x‘ir'r'. ”Sututions don‘- ire" .; fl . .- . - .. mt.“ .- I.” .r "."v€5'.- .1» To my parents “ow ' ‘ , . . ‘4.’ 5') lfif!‘ .kaJa . .n .1 , Unfortunately, ~ , “‘fl not as car. * :~ super. -» ~ I . s W ’I II' ‘I i 3' t”. to cWietely raid. -' ‘ .. v u‘ _;,_.»..-3,.,:, . . .' in". only I . ~ . It.» rr~:; than: imi‘ia‘h :1“. ”wt. ‘0' lil‘i: c’n'l in?" . , .3 .. _ ' ‘ . CuI if- T‘ 2 - .' . X ._ _ . .V--'.3".""f'. am en— “I: who lid! n) i , ‘ ‘oo ”It . 5.5.: To Dr Jamar I. mm» . -- .- A~ chairman ' 7.9-... “1m and their 71". " , . l_ »_ m zo_p<=mouz_ 4_m:< ecu co.umumgngmuc_ mexmz :o_mmowc Lou :o_ueELoL:_ u:_xmz :owm.uun v mansxs eaeg weasxs UOIQEWJO;UI I‘llIIVIlil.l|l'|[\l‘ll. ‘i‘llir 24 must adapt as societal goals change while at the same time providing the information that leads to changes in society. 2.3.3 APPLICATION TO OPERATING INFORMATION SYSTEMS What insights does this abstraction of an idealized information system provide when applied to a specific type of operating information system? To begin, there seem to be some minor deficiencies in separating the various components of the system. For example, in many ways economics revolves around a common basis of value. At first glance this might lead one to conclude that all economic statistics have a common conceptual basis. This erroneous conclusion ignores an important point of the para- digm. The needs of decision makers must feed back in the system to pro- vide the grounding for the concepts used in the data system. So the pur- pose of the systems determines the level of generality or specificity used in forming the concepts of the data system. Even for a concept as seem- ingly simple as a price, it appears that for different types of decisions different concepts are needed. Long run or strategic decisions by firms often can use data based on a concept of price that is more of an average or unit value concept, while more of a detailed specification price con- cept seems to be of greater utility for the short run or tactical deci- sions within the same firm (Riemenschneider, p. 34-35). While in an abstract sense this paradigm distinguishes between data and information, a difficulty is encountered in attempting to deter- mine the difference between data and information within the context of a specific information system. Very few decision makers or even analysts can use raw data, so almost all data are presented within a chosen format. The choice of a fonnat implies some level of interpretation of the data. 25 So formatting clouds the distinction between data and information. More importantly this low level of interpretation or formatting points to the critical nature of the communication function in any operating information system. Except in the very limited cases where a single decision maker undertakes the design and collection of data and their subsequent analysis, the usefulness of data is tied to their interpersonal transmissability. Communication theorists are concerned with the process of encoding mes- sages prior to the transmission of signals in a communication channel. All data undergo initial formatting so that they can be understood by ana- lysts, this formatting seems to be analogous to the encoding of messages before transmission. The understandability or interpersonal transmissability of data is often directly correlated with the chosen format of the data. For instance, a general politician with only a passing interest in agriculture might find a statistic labelled “hog farrowings" completely useless for a policy decision if he or she does not know the meaning of the word "farrow- ings." This same politician might be able to perform appropriate analyses and reach a decision concerning an aspect of farm policy relevant to hog farmers if this statistic were called an index of future pork production. Labelling of data is not the only aspect of formatting relevant here. Choosing the appropriate level of aggregation and the ability of users to access data as well as other related aspects are critical. Thus, when- ever the data collection process is organizationally separate from the analysis and decision making, this formatting and communication process becomes an integral part of the information system. Conceptual obsolescence is a problem for most operating infonna- tion systems and can occur in two ways. First, concepts can become obso- A 26 lete when reality changes in such a manner that the concepts are no longer representative of reality. A second type of conceptual obsolence is often more critical; this occurs when the agenda for decisions changes so the concepts of the data system are no longer pertinent to the decisions that are being made. The American Agricultural Economics Association's Eco— nomic Statistics Committee cited conceptual obsolescence as a major source of data problems in agriculture. The majority of agricultural statistics in the United States are collected around a concept of the "family farm" which has not changed in over 50 years.§/ The structure of agriculture has changed greatly during this time but the concept remains the same. Conceptual obsolescence in agricultural statistics has also come about because the policy issues facing agriculture have changed dramatically in recent years. Issues which relate to energy, the environment, consumers, and the world food situation have all had a substantial impact on agri- culture yet the data system for the sector is not designed to answer many of the questions which have arisen in response to these issues (Bonnen 1975a). 2.4 ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS The major implication of the information systems paradigm pre- sented here is that information only becomes an economically valuable commodity in the context of decision making. For those theoretical econ- omists living in a world of perfect knowledge the disclaimer must be added that information first becomes valuable under conditions of uncer- tainty. But in most practical applications consideration of uncertainty 3/ While it is true that the concept has not changed, the manner in which this concept has been operationalized has changed periodically. 27 is a fact of life. When viewed in an information systems context, information can be treated as a commodity. Kenneth J. Arrow (1962) provides a link between information as a commodity and information systems. His concern was with "inventive activity" which he equates to the production of information. Arrow's notion of inventive activity seems to be analogous to an informa-' tion system since both processes yield an output of information. In this sense, inventive activity would seem to include data design and collection in addition to the analysis of data to produce information for decision makers. ‘ Since information only acquires value in a decision making frame- work the value of decisions is a primary determinant of the value of in- formation. Therefore, the value of an information system depends on the types of decisions for which it is used and consequently on those who make the decisions. Infonnation has many characteristics which provide insights into questions concerning information system design. Once the characteristics of information as a commodity are understood it is possible to look at general used of information to get an indication of the determinants of the supply of and demand for information. While not explicitly providing a measure of the value of information, the determinants of infonnation supply and demand should illuminate some of the difficulties in deter- mining the value of information and the appropriate role of government in the provision of information. 2.4.1 CHARACTERISTICS OF INFORMATION The characteristics of information as a commodity affect its 28 allocation in the economy. Information possesses some of the attributes of public goods which lead to allocational inefficiencies when compared to purely private goods in a competitive market. The attributes of un- certainty, indivisibility, and nonappropriability all violate the classi- cal properties of purely private goods. The existence of uncertainty is inherent in our definition of information. Information is also by defi- nition indivisible. As Kenneth Boulding points out, the absence of any unit of infor- mation makes the pricing of information difficult and hence even makes it difficult to think of information as a commodity. The electrical engi- neers and data processors break information down into "bits" and this con- cept is basic to their theory of information processing. "The bit, however, abstracts completely from the content of either information or knowledge, and while it is enormously useful for telephone engineers, who have no interest in what is being said over their telephones, for the purposes of the . social system theorist we need a measure which takes account of significance and which would weight, for instance, the gossip of a teenager rather low and the communication over the hot line between Moscow and Washington rather high." (Boulding, p. 3) Geoffrey Newman (p. 486) notes two other related problems in defining in- formation in term of bits. First “bits“ may vary with the problems of the decision makers, and second even if simple factual propositions could be broken down into bits, how can theories based on deduction be broken down into bits since theories do not necessarily have a basis in fact. For our purposes the problem of nonappropriability as a property of information is particularly important because of the implications it has for market structure. Producers cannot nonnally charge for further uses of information once it is disseminated so the returns to the supplier of infonmation are not fully appropriable. As Boulding answers, only 29 things clearly appropriable can become property and be exchanged; if something cannot be property, it cannot be a commodity. The problems of appropriability of information make it a peculiar kind of property which affect its supply and demand. The question of appropriability cannot be separated from the issue of property rights for information. Copyright and patent laws make the appropriability of returns to information easier for certain types and certain uses of information but the costs of enforcement make this a reasonable alternative only in selected cases. For instance, if one pos- sesses information about a commodity that is traded in a market, one must trade in the market to get a return on the information. However, by com- pleting a transaction in the market at least the nature of the information that one possesses is released to others in the market. Thus no copyright or patent laws could prevent others from using this information. Many cases still remain, though, where the tradeoff exists between changing the mechanisms for supplying information and changing the property rights to information in order to get a more optimal allocation of resources for the production of information. Changing the supply mechanisms is for the most part easier than changing the property rights and hence our later analysis assumes that the structure of the property rights for information is relatively constant. V The incomplete appropriability of information suggests that in cases where data or information are sold to individuals that it should be presented in a manner that is somewhat ephemeral so that only those who originally pay the information supplier are likely to receive the infor- mation. If the information supplier can present it in such a way that the original purchaser of the information does not have a relatively 30 permanent document containing the information then it is more difficult for the original purchaser to pass the information along to others. For instance, Maynes, pp. 31., (p. 27) suggest the use of cable television as a means to present consumer price information which would reduce the po— tential for unauthorized resale of the information. This also suggests that any user fees charged for the information should be low enough so those who buy the information have little incentive to resell it. Reselling of information is related to the characteristic of increasing net returns in the use of information. This phenomenon stems from the indivisibility of information taken in conjunction with the high fixed costs usually associated with acquiring infonnation relative to the costs of transmitting the same information once it is acquired. The ini- tial purchasers or users of information are able to pass along the infor- mation at a cost lower than the original supplier. Increasing returns to the use of information arise as long as the value of the information is relatively constant for each subsequent use. The incomplete appropriabil- ity attribute only exacerbates the difficulties brought on by increasing returns in use, since it prevents the original supplier of information from charging for the subsequent uses of the information once it is dis- seminated. Thus, the high fixed costs of acquisition cannot be spread over all users. The fact that information only acquires value in a decision making situation gives rise to a fundamental paradox. A decision maker or pur- chaser of information does not know the exact value of the information "until it is acquired and used, but to determine precisely its value prior to buying it the purchaser must in effect obtain the information without cost. The problem caused by this paradox would be alleviated if the 31 seller retained the property rights to the information, but as was pre- viously mentioned the lack of complete appropriability is a basic charac- teristic of information. The importance of credibility and reliability of sources of data and information is stressed by this paradox. When the purchaser of the information is forced to estimate its value prior to receipt, the value is often determined from previous experience with the same supplier. Another common way to judge reliability, especially of statistical data, is through the methodology used in the data collection. This accen- tuates the critical role of documentation of statistical procedures in operating information systems. When there is no other way to estimate the value of certain kinds of data except through an assessment of the data gathering procedures, this documentation of the procedures is important. In cases where new suppliers or new users of the data arise documentation is even more essential since prior experience cannot be used to place a value on the data. Given the three types of statistical reliability im- plied by the information systems paradigm, this documentation should in- clude a statement of the concepts underlying the data, how these concepts are operationalized, as well as some notion of the statistical sampling methods used. There are further characteristics which affect both the supply and demand for information as a commodity. The production of infonnation is a risky process. The output of the production process, i.e., the in- formation, cannot be predicted perfectly from the inputs so the process has uncertainty associated with it (Arrow 1962, p. 616). For an informa- tion system this problem arises because of the nature of the decisions for which the information is to be used. The same data can be analyzed 32 to produce information that is different depending on the problematic situation. The characteristics outlined above, i.e., the riskiness of infor- mation production, the indivisibility of information, its nonappropriabil- ity, increasing returns in use, all cause the competitive model to lead to a sub-optimal allocation of resources from society's point of view for the production of information. Arrow (1962) shows that these attributes cause an underinvestment in and an underutilization of information in the free enterprise economy. The same conclusion is reached if one considers that information has many of the attributes of public goods and thus will be underproduced relative to a purely private good in a competitive system. 2.4.2 SUPPLYING INFORMATION FOR PRIVATE USE The characteristics of information outlined above create some difficulties in determining a suitable means of organization for the pro- vision of agricultural information for private sector decision making. There seem to be three basic organizational arrangements for supplying information on a given industry. Each firm could purchase information from a specialist firm, all firms could work together in data gathering, using an industry or trade association to provide the information, finally governments could gather and provide information to all of the firms. The social returns to information are not estimated in most in- stances, perhaps, because of the inherent difficulties in valuing informa- tion. However it does seem clear that the social returns to information often exceed the sum of individuals' private returns, particularly in a decentralized economic system where infonnation is needed to coordinate economic activity among firms. Without information the prospects of 33 realizing the full potential for increases in productivity from technical change in a sector would be greatly diminished. The initial work in this area by Yujiro Hayami and Wilis Peterson tends to confirm these hypotheses. Their results show that, at least at the margin, improvements in the mea- surement accuracy of data can cause increases in social welfare in a market situation, as measured by losses of consumer surplus, beyond the benefits estimated by merely summing the individual private benefits. While in an aggregate sense data improvements might be in the over- all interest of society, it is clear that any improvements in an informa- tion system generally benefit some groups more than others or benefit certain groups at the expense of others. Thus, it is likely that improve- ments or changes in data design will be non-Pareto better. This stresses the nonnative tone associated with any decisions in this area. As in most public choice situations tradeoffs between different groups must be weighed to determine the sagacity of any improvements in a public information sys- tem. It should also be noted that arguments presented in this section begin with the implicit assumption that social benefits to information do exceed private benefits, i.e., positive externalities exist. From this starting point it is then easier to discuss economic considerations in evaluating different information systems. While related to questions con- cerning the economics of information, the following discussion is perhaps best described as dealing with the economics of information systems. This subtle distinction is necessary to maintain the generality of the results and to avoid the overwhelming difficulties associated with determining the social value of information for each existing or pr0posed information sys- tem. 34 Of particular interest is the effect of an industry's market structure on organization to supply information. Since there are gener- ally high fixed costs in information production relative to the variable dissemination costs, one might expect a firm to exploit these decreasing average costs by monopolizing the collection and dissemination of informa- tion for an industry. The incanplete appropriability of the returns to information production is one factor which decreases the likelihood of the development of information specialist firms. Also, as Oliver Williamson notes, the opportunistic behavior of firms reduces the probability of existence of these information provision specialists. There is a risk that any firm specializing in information provision will selectively dis- tort the information it sells. Since the information is not easily veri- fied, usually only by collecting original data again, exchange between firms in an industry and the specialist firm will fail. Thus, the impor- tance of credibility, pointed to by the fundamental paradox of information, suggests that as long as firms are opportunistic in their bahavior, it is unlikely that firms will purchase information from a profit seeking firm specializing in infonnation. Recent hearings by the United States House of Representatives Small Business Committee concerning the manipulation of meat prices by the National Provisioner Daily Market Service, a private meat price data col- : lection firm, suggest that very little incentive is needed by specialist firms to distort the information it provides. Testimony by the committee staff investigator stated that the National Provisioner Daily Market Ser- vice reported prices where only a limited number of trades or no trades ‘ at all took place. The implied incentive in this case was to maintain sales of data to the specialist firm's customers. 35 As the number of transactions in the meat industry declined it became more difficult to report prices for all types, weights, and grades of meat. Instead of admitting this, the National Provisioner appears to have continued reporting prices based on a small number of transactions simply to give the appearance that it was doing its job. These actions appear to have been undertaken to maintain customers. While these allega- tions have not been proven it is suggestive of problems arising from the ' reliance on specialist firms for information (United States House of Re- presentatives, pp. 245-292). The argument against specialist finns hinges on the notion that these firms will be opportunistic in their behavior, which Williamson de- fines as seeking self-interest with guile. If opportunistic behavior is not assumed, then the risk of strategic misrepresentation disappears and specialization in the production of information is possible. This stresses both the need for an unbiased, nonopportunistic firm or organization to collect market information as well as the importance of reliability and accuracy in data collection. information production also makes the possibility for individual firm production of market information less likely, except in the case of mono- poly. Since there is only one firm in the industry in a monopoly situa- tion, the benefits of any investment in market information for that indus- try accrue directly to the mon0polist. Hence, it can justify its expense and can expect to reap the benefits of any investment in information to manage the industry. Advertising by farm input firms is another example of some of the problems of information specialization. The advertising function is ‘l‘ .l‘ IE 36 usually a case of specialization of information provision within part of a larger firm. Here the obvious incentive is for the advertising branch strategically to misrepresent or distort the information it provides to farmers in order to increase the profits of the firm. Thus, the informa- tion provided by advertising is of limited use to the farmer. For the' most part, the useful portion of the information is only that which can be easily verified such as price, product availability, and those quality characteristics identifiable by in5pection. While truth in advertising laws can be used to alleviate problems of gross misrepresentation by op- portunistic firms it is unlikely that these will eliminate all biases. When the advertising concerns product characteristics that can only be determined through experience, such as the durability of a piece of farm machinery, rather than by simple inspection, the opportunities for mis- representation multiply. The public good attributes of information suggest that some form of collective action in information production should lead to an increase in social welfare. .However, no indication is given from the characteris- tics of information, per se, as to whether a voluntarily organized private effort is possible rather than government intervention. In making this choice the theory of groups can provide some insights. If industry is viewed as a group of finns and information as a public good, then Mancur Olson's theory of groups can be used to show the effect of economic structure on information supply. Olson shows that the ability to organize a group depends on whether the individual member is able to obtain benefits in excess of costs. Olson has shown that some small groups can organize to provide a public good without any benefits other than those provided by the good itself. In cases where groups are 37 very small, i.e., where each member gets a major proportion of the total benefits of the public good simply because the members of the group are few in number, this public good can often be provided by the voluntary action of the individuals in the group purely on the basis of the self- interest of the group members. This suggests that as industry structure moves toward oligopoly that market information is more likely to be pro- vided by an industry association and that government collection of data for private use in the industry is probably not necessary. As groups get larger some other incentive such as government sub- sidy or selective benefits in the form of private goods might be necessary to organize a group to provide public goods. Since a public good is such that use by one individual does not preclude the consumption by another individual, even small groups will fail to provide an amount of public good near the amount provided in the case where information possessed the characteristics of a purely private good. The divergence between these two amounts increases as group size increases (Olson). The conclusion can be drawn from this that government intervention might be appropriate to achieve a desired level of information production as an industry be- comes more atomistic. This would also force some of the "free riders" in an industry, who would use information provided by a trade association but would not support the group financially, to pay for the use of the information through taxes. It must also be kept in mind that government information provision subsidized by tax revenues would force some taxpayers who do not benefit from the information to pay for it anyway. To summarize the arguments about the relationship of economic structure to the supply of information for private use: First the problems of indivisibility and nonappropriability make private data collection and 38 analysis unlikely under the conditions of a competitive market structure. As an industry becomes more and more concentrated, it will be increasingly in the self-interest of the firms in the industry to supply information for their own use and hence government provision of information for pri- vate use is less and less necessary. However, as the industry structure moves toward more atomistic competition, then the argument for government provision of data collection and analysis can be made on the grounds of improved efficiency in the allocation of resources because the industry is net likely to provide an amount any where near Optimum, assuming that there are net social returns to the information in addition to the sum of the private returns. 2-4. 3. INFORMATION FOR PUBLIC use The previous discussion centered on providing data and information For private sector decision making. For public sector decision making, da ta collection and analysis is by definition a government activity. GoVernment information provision is usually relied on to assure accurate and credible information for public policy decisions and to avoid the s‘:"‘ategic misrepresentation of information supplied by the private sector ‘PQF public decisions. This is not to say that government data and infor- Wag tion is always beyond reproach. When data are used as performance mea- S“ has for public policies it is easy for the data to become politicized and lose credibility. Even the private use of data can cause it to be “()1 ‘lticized. Private sector lobbies have politicized some public data used in critical private sector decisions, e.g. the use of the Consumer 1: hi ce Index in collective bargaining has tended to enhance the political ““essure on this data preventing timely modifications to maintain or 39 Somewhat similar improve the reliability of the Consumer Price Index pr1vate sector pressures have developed around the USDA measure of aggre- gate farm income. Pol1tic1z1ng data rarely involves changing the numbers, per se Usually more subtle methods are found such as speeding up publicat1on of favorable data or delaying unfavorable data to mesh more closely with polf cy pr0posals, controlling the format of the data to 1nsure that tech- nical interpretations fit with policy pronouncements or the fa1lure to make changes in existing data concepts or definitions to fit reality since these changes might make a situation look better or worse and thus make the current government look bad. Comments on personnel and other changes in the Federal Stat1st1cal System of the United States in the early 19705 by Phil1p M Hauser show that the integrity and credibility of data can be affected without actu- Some of these events, such as appointing political a 1 13' changing numbers. . cronies to head statistical agencies and the cancellation of regular sur- veys while yielding no evidence of direct political man1pulat1on of data, least suggested possible impropriety and thus reduced the cred1b1l1ty at In agriculture the political difficulties encountered in O f the data. I'"anging the definition of a farm gives an indication of why 1t 15 often I.) Q 1 itically difficult to make improvements in data once they have become ‘F‘i "mly institutionalized (Hildreth and Worden). One should not paint too bleak a picture for government prov1ded data for public decisions since the alternative is often much worse Many ther types of difficulties are encountered when the government relies on The current debate phi vate sector information to make policy dec151ons P“ the Un1ted States over the level of natural gas reserves points to the 40 Problems of strategic misrepresentation of data supplied by private firms for public use (James N. Miller). Therefore, in designing a government information system various efforts to guard against politicization of data should be considered. Some of the important means of avoiding politiciza- tion of data include the complete documentation Of methodologies used in obtaining data, the encouragement of ties between government statisticians, economists, and other analysts and academic and other nongovernment pro- ' fessionals in these fields, the selection of leaders Of statistical agen- cies on merit not political acceptability, and an attempt to maintain appropriate distance between policy formulation and evaluation and the collection of statistics. In this last case we are not necessarily argu- ing for a separate statistical agency, only that the functions of data conection and policy formulation be quite distinct within an agency to a\Hlficl even the appearance of imprOpriety. 2 - 4. 4. THE DEMAND FOR INFORMATION The value of information is discovered only in a decision making Qt)“text, so the demand for information is determined by its value in the dQQision process of firms or government. The value of information, then, ‘T 3 not known with certainty until it is Obtained and used, so problems a“? se in estimating the demand for information. Firms that are risk ad- VQ "se will tend to demand less information because of the uncertainty of t heir returns, a priori, to investments in information. As industrialization occurs in a country, production processes b‘acome specialized so more informtion is required for firm and market Q'Oordination. Thus, for the same investment in market information, returns ‘10 the firm should increase as an industry becomes more specialized. As 41 industry structure becomes concentrated, the returns to information invest— ment for private use can be captured by the small number of firms in the This ability to capture returns to information investment also industry. At the other end affect the demand for information by an individual firm. of the industrial structure spectrum where there are many independent firms, as in agriculture, the amount of private sector investment in producing information will probably approach zero since only a small portion of the returns can be captured by any one firm. In this case the public returns to information in the form of better coordination would probably exceed the private returns. On this same continuum, the public use demand for i nfor'mation will decline as one moves away from atomistic markets then increase as information to monitor and regulate monopolistic industries is necessary. This is expecially true where regulation on monOpolies throngh antitrust laws is viewed as a socially desirable goal. The need for data on monopolistic industries raises the additional q“'esdzion of public access to data collected by highly concentrated indus- 1: hi es and monopolies. There is a public interest in this type Of infor- m ati on which should temper any discussion of confidentiality and disclo- Sub . ‘3. Data on these types Of firms are Often sensit1ve because Of the Q thentrated nature of the industry and the immediate effects of any ‘F i i"hrs actions on the market. However, this makes this same data ex— th ' Ql‘nely critical for public decisions. Thus the benefits to society of t hQ preservation of privacy, particularly among corporations, must be Q i shed against the information needs of public policy decision makers (BQHnen 1975b. Pp. 101-102). The ability to capture returns is related to the ability to use ‘“formation. A farmer who has sold all of the farm's grain for a year f ' )\¢ ES 42 will find further information on grain prices of little immediate value, indeed, it has been known to lead to high blood pressure and other aggra- The ability to use market information is also related to the Therefore, vat'ions. accessability of sellers to different buyers of the commodity. the market area covered (in terms of number of buyers) by an information system should be related to the demand for the market information. A farmer in California is not likely‘to be as concerned with spot market prices in New York as those prices in California. This question of acces- sabi ‘l ity to markets must be answered to define the area of coverage for certain kinds Of market statistics. It should not be implied from this that markets are not related or prices from other areas cannot enter into the decisions of farmers in a given area. However it seems reasonable to aSsume that sellers would be most interested in the prices from the spe- (:1 fi c markets where their sales occur. Up to this point we have dealt in terms Of the effect of indus- tr»: al structure on information 'in a reasonably Obvious fashion. There is a More subtle effect which runs in the Opposite direction, i.e., the e"T'irect of information on industrial structure. Earlier some of the eco- hQ'hic characteristics of information were mentioned. These can affect 15‘ _ i "‘111 size and industrial structure. The riskiness of information produc- t‘i On is Often such that outside insurance cannot be purchased to Offset that risk. Self-insurance in the form Of diversification is Often used ‘9 deal with such risk. This suggests that in order for a firm to be ab‘le to produce information through data collection and analysis, it must b5 large enough to internalize the risk Of losses in information gather- ‘ “9. Thus, information production is usually done by large firms and ‘ arge firm size is generally related tO industrial concentration. 43 The indivisibility of information also can affect industrial con- centration, in that it leads to increasing returns in the use of informa4 Roy Radner notes that "the acquisition Of information Often involves tion. a 'set-up cost'; i.e., the resources needed to Obtain the information may be independent of the scale of the production process in which the infor- Robert Wilson calls this "informational econo- mation is used" (p. 457). mies of scale," and notes that this phenomenon is self-reinforcing in that a higher scale Of operation justifies better information acquisition and increased information acquisition will justify a higher scale of Operation. Hence . economies in the acquisition Of information can increase firm size Theoretically this will occur as long as infor- t0 the point Of monOpOly. While Radner and Wilson seem mati on is acquired in an Optimal fashion. to have horizontal firm structure in mind, as Williamson (p. 86) notes, the same argument can be made for vertical integration in many cases. Thus . indivisibilities in information and the resulting increasing re- turns in use of information can also affect the vertical structure of a s . . . . QtI‘lzor by providing an 1ncentive for vert1cal integration solely to re- d u Ce uncertainty. The arguments presented in this section demonstrate that it is not a political or bureaucratic accident that government collects more QTiailed statistics and does more analysis for private use on highly com- QtZitive, atomistic industries, such as agriculture, than it does in more QQ"boentrated industries such as steel or autos. Publicly collected data fab private management decision making have played a substantial role in the great increases in agricultural productivity in the United States “Var the past century. Society has captured the returns to improved re- SOUrce use in agriculture through lower food costs and the availability 44 (H much of the former farm labor force for nonagricultural production. The greater returns to society through improvement in resource allocation from better public information on competitive industries when compared to concentrated industries provide the primary basis for allocating public monies for statistical systems to support private decisions. Hence, the logical allocation of public resources not just for public decision needs. but for private uses follows from the nature of the industrial structure itself (Bonnen 1976, pp. 14-15). 2.4. 5 - INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF INFORMATION Modern economic theory also has been particularly deficient in deal ing with distributional issues while concentrating on problems of in"Ocative efficiency. Just as uncertainty is usually assumed away in models of resource allocation, the distribution of income is Often assum- ‘3‘: lto be Optimal to begin with and hence is not treated. The connection betiween the distribution Of information and the distribution of income Seems to be a key but Often-overlooked notion. As Lester C. Thurow argues, "The factors that cause changes in the distribution of income are themselves distributions. The distribution Of education and training affects the distribution of income. Thus, to adequately study the American distribution Of income, it is necessary to develop methods of explaining the distribution Of income in terms of the distribution of causal factors which influence it.“ (p. 261) “‘Formation is clearly one Of those causal factors to which Thurow refers and thus the study Of income distribution requires an understanding Of the distribution of information. The distribution of income can be discussed at two different levels a“cl the types and impacts of information will differ at each of these 45 First, one can consider the overall or size distribution of in- levels. Secondly, there is the question Of income come in the entire society. distribution among given individuals or groups Of individuals within society. This distinction may be viewed as a macro-micro delineation of the problem. Keeping in mind that we are considering information in a systems context, the distinction between data and information has important im- plications for income distribution. Data require analysis and interpre- tati on in the context of a specific decision to become information (Bonnen In general, a more equal distribution Of data among mem- 1975a, p. 758). bers of society is likely to have quite different effects on income than an equal distribution of information because of the disparity in analyti- Mpabilities Of those receiving the data. It is this analytical capability that Thurow and others seem to have in mind when discussing the relationship between the distribution Of education and training and the distribution of income. Insofar as education provides superior data h terpretati on capability among members Of society, one would expect that I: he distribution Of education and hence information would in turn be re- 1 g . . ted to the distribution of income. This expectation is supported by ‘t: he literature (Thurow). This relationship between education and income has been directed Dh‘i marily at the most general level, i.e., its effect on the size distri- Eution of income in society. As Donald M. Lamberton (p. 462) notes, the SQ heral expectation of improved information is to reduce inequality in DQ‘Wer, wealth, and income. HOwever, it is at this most general societal ~‘e‘lel that improved information is Often least likely to cause the desired reduction Of inequality because of the different capacities of firms and 46 individuals to use or acLOLthg information that they receive, even given the same capability to analyze and interpret data. When new information becomes available to both concentrated buyers and dispersed sellers, the buyers are at a great advantage. Not only dO the buyers have greater analytical capabilities and capacity to use information but they also have a greater capacity to take counteraction. For example, published prices can also make price fixing agreements between buyers easier to maintain. While there is no evidence Of this actually'happening, it is conceivable that an agricultural information system could encourage price fixing among Oligopsonistic buyers Of agricultural conmodities. Furthermore, in a recent unpublished survey of nonrespondents to U.S. Department of Agri- culture surveys, the two comments most frequently given by farmers for their refusal to respond were that 1) the surveys benefit others more than farmers and 2) the surveys hurt farmers. Whether or not these statements are completely true is debatable but at least it suggests the possibility 0f data being used against the more dispersed traders in a market. These insights have important implications concerning the relation- 5hlp of information to income distribution. First, since the value Of in- 1"ovulation arises only in its use, the capacity to use or act on informa- tion will have a significant effect on income distribution. Second, eco- nomic structure again influences the distributional consequences Of infor- mation. Insofar as the size Of firms are related to market structure, e.g. , flmS in OligOpOlistic industries are assumed large enough so their deci- lenS will influence the market, large firms probably have both superior a"i”.Y’Cic capability and a greater capacity to use or act on information than do small firms. These larger firms can be expected to use their superior information to influence in its favor transactions with smaller ‘7» Hi '{n '1‘ 47 less informed firms, so the subsequent income distribution will favor larger more concentrated firms. The distribution of income is primarily determined by the outcome Of the market in the private sector (Weisbrod, p. 2178). SO as information affects market structure and behavior, it also affects income distribution. This reliance on market transactions to determine income distri- buti on highlights the importance Of the distribution Of information be- tween individuals in an exchange situation. The problems here are at a more micro-level than those discussed earlier and the effects of the dis- tribution of information are on the distribution Of income between the individuals involved. This is similar to the market failure brought on by what is called information impactedness by Williamson. He argues that this phenomenon, ". . . is attributable to the pairing Of uncertainty with Opportunism. It (information impactedness) exists in circumstances in which one of the parties to an exchange is much better informed than is the other regarding the underlying conditions germane to the trade, and the second party cannot achieve parity except at great cost--because he cannot rely on the first party to disclose the informa- tion in a fully candid manner." (p. 14) When trading occurs under the circumstances of asymmetrical information, one can only expect a redistribution of income in favor of those who pos- 5855 the supperior information when compared to the case when information Impactedness does not exist. In the previous section, it was argued that the governmental col- 1ECtion of data and its production Of information for agriculture could be Justified in terms Of improved resource allocation. Burton Weisbrod (p. 179) makes the point that income redistribution can be undertaken in a number of ways including the use Of redistributional "side effects“ Of P°HCles that are usually considered to have efficient resource allocation 48 as their goal and not income redistribution. To the extent that govern- ment wishes to redistribute income in favor of agriculture, one can argue that many of the programs to improve the information system for agricul- ture are achieving this Objective, even though many of the programs are aimed at the resource allocation problems caused by uncertainty. However, even those programs which tend to equalize the access of information in trades, such as price and production estimates, might not have desirable income distribution effects because of the market structure in agriculture. The predominance Of atomistic producers and concentrated buyers in this sector may prevent any major redistributions Of income between buyers and sellers because Of the superior analytical capability and ability to use government produced information possessed by the larger firms in the agri- cultural sector. However, tO the extent that government research and data collection tend to equalize the information of individuals involved in ex- changes Of agricultural commodi ties, there will be a change in the distri- buti on of income toward greater equality. Many programs have tended to achieve this desired income distributional change. For example, the land grant college system and extension education programs probably have increased the analytical capability of farmers relative to those with “Men they deal, and the establishment and regulation Of futures markets 91 Ve farmers a greater capacity to use or act on information that did not previously exist for farmers. The major arguments Of this chapter suggest that there exists a Chronic or absolute underinvestment in information production because Of the economic characteristics of information. Perhaps of greater impor- tance are the implications Of these theoretical findings for the relative distribution Of investments in data collection and analysis. In those H *H Li "'1 u. f:' "l is. rx: 4 49 cases where changes in the information system benefit some groups more than others or at the expense Of different groups, a basis is required for determining which changes represent the best use Of government re- sources. The criteria for making improved government investments in data collection and analysis follow from the market structure of the industry which benefits from the information and from the effects Of the informa- tion on income distribution. Using these criteria it is possible to es- tablish relative priorities for public investment in information. Wise public investment in data collection and analysis should help to equalize the information Of individuals involved in transactions and thus will lead to greater equity in the income distribution. 2.5 SUMMARY In order to evaluate an Operating information system it is parti- cularly useful to have a framework to serve as a guide in structuring the evaluation. For the purposes Of this study an information systems para- digm provides the framework for the subsequent analysis. The main focus of this paradigm is with problem solving and to the extent that problem solving decision making requires information from a variety Of disciplines this framework is multidisciplinary. An information system as presented here has three major parts: 1) a data system which includes data concepts, the operationalization or definition of these concepts and the measurement Of these defined concepts to produce data; 2) an analysis or interpretation step to transform data into information for decisions; and 3) the decision maker. When applied to Operating information systems this paradigm has some minor deficiencies 'b 12.5 , , i'nh 1' w I c: 95.. ME CECE IAI- *le 50 with respect to the formatting and communication of data and information. Problems of conceptual Obsolescence become apparent in Operating data systems when the concepts used in the data system are no longer represen- tative of reality or when the agenda for decisions changes so the concepts are not pertinent for the types Of decisions that must be made using the data. The primary economic implication Of this paradigm is that infor- mation only becomes valuable in the context of decision making. The pub- lic good characteristics Of information coupled with the implied condition that information can be treated as a commodity within a decision making framework has major consequences for understanding the role of government in producing information. With these characteristics and conditions in mind, two variables or relationships become critical in the design or redesign of an informa- tion system. The first Of these is the configuration Of the relevant eco- nomic sectors. Economic structure affects the supply and demand for infor— mation in both the public and private sectors, has consequences on the distribution of information and is critical in understanding the appro- priate role Of government in providing information. The second key theoretical relationship considered was that be- tween the distribution Of information and income distribution. Economics Often neglects the effects of the distribution Of information on the dis- tribution Of income but, in many instances, equity concerns lie behind the reason for allocating public funds for data collection and analysis. CHAPTER 3 REVIEW OF LITERATURE ON AGGREGATE FARM INCOME DATA 3.1 INTRODUCTION A review Of the relevant literature for this study is in order. A comprehensive treatment of the literature on the economics Of informa- tion or information systems in general is not intended. These were covered in part in the development of the conceptual framework in the preceding chapter. Instead, this literature review will focus on some of the recent literature on aggregate farm income accounting. The intention is to concentrate on the important works related to this study and to point out the relevant aspects of these for this analysis. These earlier studies provide a set Of recommendations for farm income data improvements but their approach and intent often differ from the type of analysis un- dertaken in this study. After examining the USDA farm income data in an information systems context, it should be possible to set priorities among the improvements recommended in the earlier studies. Within the area Of aggregate farm income accounting two aspects will be emphasized. First, some Of the recent reports and evaluations Of USDA farm income data will be summarized. Second, some alternative con- ceptualizations Of farm income or economic well being Of farmers will be examined. 51 H' 1 I'd- '_1 (t) L“.. «'12 h lE‘. are ll“; is 52 3.2 ANALYSES OF FARM INCOME DATA 3.2.1. GROVE Ernest W. Grove was one Of the first agricultural economists to question the relevance of a concept Of farm income to the current needs of data users. Grove's focus was rather narrow and concerned the apprOpri- ateness Of the realized net farm income concept as Opposed to the total net farm income concept. Data on both are estimated by the U.S. Depart- ment of Agriculture. The concept of realized farm income does not consider increases or decreases in farm output inventories as part of income, while the total farm income concept does account for the value of crap and livestock in- ventory change. Grove argues that there are six major deficiencies in the realized farm income concept that make it less desirable than the total fanm income concept. First, since total farm income is needed for the Department of Commerce's estimates Of farm product, the publication of both realized and total farm income can cause confusion among unSOphisti- cated users of the data. This dilemma suggests that understandability Of data is an important consideration in data system design. Second, he argues that the realized farm income concept is con- trary to generally accepted practice and the theory Of income measurement. This stems from the usual notion in economics that increases in inventories are actually a form of savings from current income and real income can only arise out Of current production. In part the distinction between realized and total farm income is somewhat analogous to accounting on a cash or accrual basis. However, the analogy is not exact since producer owned purchased input inventories are not included in total net farm income. 50 at least by analogy it seems that Grove is arguing that the accepted theory 53 and practice in income measurement is to account for income on more of an accrual basis. While accrual accounting dominates other sectors of the economy because Of Ferderal income tax rules, it is clear that cash ac- :counting is much more prevalent in agriculture. Harrison notes that 98% of all 1969 farm tax returns used cash accounting methods. But Grove is correct in saying, in effect, that the accrual method is the most accepted, method in the sense that the National Income Accounts Of the Department of Commerce are on an accrual basis. Grove seems to imply this when he traces the develOpment Of the total net income series. This series arose out of a need by the Commerce Department to have a measure of farm in- come more closely in line with its accounts. The third Objection that Grove has to realized farm income is that it provides an undesirable choice Of statistics even among sophisticated users. Grove Observed that the realized income figures were used by de- cision makers in USDA except in those cases where the total income data better proved the point that these decision makers were trying to make; so that having a choice Of two series might tend to confuse some issues. This argument is certainly not unique to farm income data and applies to almost any data sets which measure similar phenomena. SO the usefulness of this argument alone is somewhat suspect. The fourth Objection arises indirectly from measurement difficul- ties in estimating the value of inventory change. Grove claims that since physical inventories are the residual Of production less marketings and that production is measured with more relative accuracy than market- ings, then total income is more accurate than realized income. In the case of total income, any errors in estimating marketings are Offset by 54 changes in inventories since inventories must equal production plus be- ginning inventories less marketings and home consumption. C. Kyle Randall, in his comment on Grove's article, points out that it is not always as easy to measure total income since production is not measured for meat animals. SO inventories here tend to be more difficult to estimate. Related to this, and shown in Breimyer's comment to the Grove paper, is the difficulty in valuing inventories. The inelasticity Of demand for agricultural products means that using average yearly prices to value in- ventories tends to overvalue large year end inventories and undervalue small inventories. These phenomena also, as Harold F. Breimyer suggests, tend to exaggerate year tO year swings in the income actually received by farmers when compared to total net farm income published by USDA. This tends to refute another of Grove's Objections to the realized income concept, that being that it has resulted in an unrealistic smoothing out of farm income estimates by eliminating increases and decreases in output that are added to or taken from inventory. The smoothing occurs because inventory change is not considered in the realized farm income concept, hence this form Of forced saving from current production is not counted. Breimyer's point that large inventories are overvalued using the current methods also re- duces the significance of Grove's other Objection, that over decades when aggregate inventories are increasing an omission Of income occurs by using the realized farm income concept. For the purposes of this study the measurement problems associated with realized farm income are not as critical as those involved in the first three Of Grove's.objections which suggest that there might be diffi- culties with the concept used by USDA in making policy decisions. While 55 his case is far from convincing, Grove at least raises the question Of conceptual relevance which is a first step in understanding the problems that should be considered in any prOposed redesigning of the farm income information system. 3.2.2 TASK FORCE ON FARM INCOME AND CAPITAL ACCOUNTING 1972 ‘ In 1972 a Task Force Of U.S. Department Of Agriculture economists and statisticians headed by Eldon Weeks completed the first comprehensive evaluation Of the department's farm income and capital accounting data. In addition to the final Task Force Report (Weeks, g5, p1,, 1972), numer- ous other publications resulted from this study, e.g. Weeks 1971, Weeks 1972, Carlin and Handy, Carlin and Smith. These will all be considered as a single develOpment in this literature review, except for those which summarize the Task Force's recommended alternative accounting system which will be dealt with in the following section on alternative concep- tualizations. Unless otherwise noted the following discussion Of this development will be based on the Final Task Force Report (Weeks, 35, 31., 1972). The Task Force report covered the basic accounting for aggregate farm inputs, outputs, capital, farm Operator inputs and to a more limited extent the distribution Of these aggregates by farm size, type and loca- tion. For the purposes of this study the capital accounting aspects will not be considered except as these relate to farm income. More important are the areas not covered by the Task Force. Given the information sys- tem paradigm that provides the conceptual framework for this study, a serious shortcoming of the 1972 Task Force was their explicit failure to consider farm income accounting designed specifically to aid decision 56 making. "Finally, possibilities of accounting for institutional mechanisms designed to facilitate or exercise decision making and control were considered out Of scope for the pgrposes Of this Task Force." (Weeks, 31,131., 1972, p. While it may be true that the 1972 Task Force was directed to stop its analysis at the data output stage of the information system, it does not relieve them of the necessity to consider how the data are ultimately used in order to make apprOpriate recommendations concerning the concepts to be used in redesigning the data system. The first step in understanding the 1972 Task Force report is to look at some Of their assumptions used in evaluating the current account- ing system. This is also significant since much of the analysis in the later chapters of this study will at least implicitly test the validity of some of these assumptions. The Task Force assumes three major purposes for an aggregate farm sector accounting system (Weeks, 33, 31,, 1972, p. 5). First, the system should describe the major economic features of the farming sector when presented in aggregate terms. Implied in this is that the concepts of data system.should bear a close correspondence to the reality of the farming sector in order to be useful. The second assumption is that the system should yield aggregate and individual series which are measures Of performance for the farm sector for both public and private uses. The final general assumption is that the system should provide data which is easily compared with other sectors of the economy. This would seem to imply that these types Of comparisons are useful in public and private decisions. From these three general assumptions six more specific assumptions 57 were made concerning improvements in the current farm income and capital accounting system. First, the current system should not be abandoned, i.e., any recommended system should not be substituted for the current series. This at least implicitly assumes an almost unlimited budget for farm income data provision in the short run. Second, any recommended system should be readily reconcilable with the Department Of Commerce's National Income and Product Accounts. Third, the system should be for- matted in such a manner that the data can be used in national input out- put models. Fourth, the basic farm income and capital accounts should provide the basis for describing the performance Of the farm sector through time. Fifth, the data system should have a conceptual basis that allows for easy cross sector and within sector comparisons. Sixth, the system should distinguish between farm businesses and farm households and between the long and short run while reflecting the unique characteristics of the farming sector. The major difficulty for the purposes Of this study with the as- sumptions outlined in the Task Force Report is that it is never stated why these Specific assumptions are made or on what ground the assumptions are based. SO before one can establish priorities for improving the current farm income data system using the Task Force recommendations, it is necessary to assess the relevance Of these assumptions in an informa- tion systems context. This topic will be addressed later. After presenting a recommended accounting framework, the Task Force appraised the existing USDA accounting formats for farm income, us- ing the recommended framework as a norm. The farm income data series were evaluated along three separate lines: 1) overall format, 2) the concep- tual basis of the most important series and 3) the linkages between ‘ 58 series. In their appraisal Of the overall format, the Task Force con- cluded that the farm income accounting format does not resemble the formats used in other sectors or countries and does not yield measures Of perfor- mance similar to those found in other sectors. This arises in part be- cause much Of the capital formation in agriculture takes place on the farm with the expenses being measured as current production expenses. Thus, the input and output sides of the current accounts are inconsistent. and the distinction between the production and capital accounts are un- clear. Certain conceptual problems arise within specific components of the farm income data that cause difficulties in using the farm income series. The 1972 Task Force cited five Of these problem components that relate to farm income. Government payments can be treated in two basic ways in the accounting system. Direct government payments can be thought of as compensation to farm businesses for the production of public goods or as income transfers tO farm families. Since the costs of compliance to the programs are currently considered as production expenses, an in- consistency arises when government payments are treated as income trans- fers. 50 depending on the concept Of production expenses used, the treatment of government payments might be different. Farm housing is another component which causes some conceptual difficulties. The maintenance and operation costs of farm housing are treated as production expenses, so it is necessary to consider the gross rental value of farm housing as farm output in order to be consistent. Under alternative accounting systems this treatment of farm housing might be different depending on whether one includes housing as part Of the Output of the farm sector. For instance, under the national income and 59 and product accounting formats, one might wish to consider farm housing as part of the real estate sector. If this were implemented, then it would be necessary to change the maintenance and Operation costs of farm housing to the real estate sector rather than the farm sector. Depreciation was the third problem identified by the Task Force. In addition to the problems associated with using book value or replace- ment value in measuring capital consumption a further difficulty arises because Of the own account capital formation on farms. As noted earlier, own account capital formation in the farming sector is generally not ac- counted for in the current data system. SO depreciation using either book value or replacement value is understated in the existing series. The conceptual basis of the inventory measurement in farm income also poses a dilemma when the current system is considered. Questions arise because of the content of some of the inventories. For example, beef breeding herds, dairy herds and laying flocks are all considered as part of the current livestock inventories when these are actually capital items in most uses. SO the current accounts might reflect changes in capital items when inventory change is measured. Under alternative con- ceptualizations one might also want inventories Of work-in-progress in addition to finished goods, both Of which are reported for other sectors. The Task Force recommended that work-in-progress, such as cattle on feed and crops in pre4harvest stages of develOpment, should be included in the linventory change measured for the farm income accounts. A final quandary pointed out by the Task Force was in the area of measuring unsold output. The current farm income accounts do not provide a measure Of total output of the farm sector. Without a measure of this, increases in cash receipts or purchased inputs could be interpreted as 60 changes in industry size and/or structure. But in reality, these might only reflect an increase in specialization. For instance, feed grain farmers raise fewer livestock and sell the grain they had previously fed to livestock. Output in this case is sold and shows up in the accounts as cash receipts for the feed grain farmer and a production expense for the livestock feeder but the total production Of feed grains did not increase. Thus the conclusion that a better accounting of intermediate products is necessary formeasuring aspects such as the productivity and size of the farming sector. Definitional and conceptual difficulties arise when the relation- ships between the various components and series of the farm income data system are examined. The linkage between returns to resources in farming, as measured by realized gross and net farm income, total net farm incOme, and personal income of the farm population highlights one of the major problems in the current system. In tying these series together it is assumed that for every farm there is only one farm Operator. This seems to be a rather tenuous assumption and makes it quite difficult to assess the impact Of the changing tenure structure in agriculture. In the formal accounting sense there are very few linkages between the current accounts in the farm income series and the capital accounts in the balance sheet series. The problems associated with inventory and de- preciation concepts and definition weaken the linkages between current land capital accounts” Gross farm income is derived mainly from ESCS estimates of sales of commodities, government payments, and imputed nonmoney income, while production expenses are estimated on a national basis primarily from census benchmarks, ESCS prices paid, and industry data. Thus, the 61 empirical linkages between these two aspects are also tenuous. The fact that some production expenses for one type Of farmer can be cash receipts _for another only complicates these linkages. SO this system of indepen- dent estimation Of income and expenses may cause the linkages between the series to be less direct. In considering the various disaggregations and distributions Of farm income the linkages in the system vary from quite direct to nonexis- tent. The disaggregation Of cash receipts by state is very direct since prices and sales are estimated at the state level. However, on the ex- pense side disaggregations are based on much more limited data, since ex- penses are first estimated at the national level. The distribution of income and expenses by sale class is based on Census Of Agriculture bench- marks, hence this series has a number of consequent measurement problems in intercensal years. However, this series for the most part provides useful information as judged by the Task Force. The disaggregation of these sales class distributions by state or region is not even attempted by USDA, suggesting rather weak linkages between these aspects. The Task Force also notes that no attempt is made on a regular basis to distribute farm income and expenses by type of farm. A lack of appropriate data is blamed but they do not conjecture why these data do not exist. Perhaps the conceptual problems associated with determining Vpreciselv what constitutes a certain type of farm leads to this data gap. Given the probelms USDA encountered in redefining a "farm" (Hildreth and Worden), one would expect similar problems in defining a "cash-grain farm" or most other types Of farms. All in all the 1972 Task Force made a significant contribution in suggesting improvements in the USDA farm income extimates. However, 62 various reorganizations within ESCS: Economics and revisions Of the cur- rent farm income data series has precluded the implementation Of very many of the Task Force recommendations (Guebert). For the purposes of this study, two major criticisms Of the 1972 Task Force Report are apparent. First, in making recommendations for improvements, no basis was provided for establishing priorities within their suggested accounting framework to guide those who would wish to im- plement these recommendations in an incremental fashion rather than as a whole package. While the task force did recommend that as much as possible be done in implementing the alternative accounting system over a two year period and that any residual work be prioritized at the end of two years, a means for setting priorities was not presented. Second, and even more significant, was the fact that the Task Force assumed certain purposes for a farm income accounting system without determining if these purposes suited the users Of the data. 3.2.3 TASK FORCE ON FARM INCOME ESTIMATES 1975 In 1975 a second Task Force comprised primarily of non-U.S. De- partment of Agriculture employees was established to evaluate the Farm Income estimates. It did not examine the overall income and capital accounts, as did the earlier Task Force. The "Report Of Task Force on Farm Income Estimates" (Hildreth, 31, 31,) will be summarized in the fol- lowing paragraphs. The exceptions tO this will be some Of the recommen- dations of the Task Force which refer to alternative conceptualizations Of farm income which will be summarized in the next section. The 1975 Task Force was primarily interested in reviewing the methods and techniques for estimating farm income. Hence most of their 63 recommendations centered around these type of improvements. The formation Of this Task Force was prompted by the large revisions required between the January and July, 1974 estimates Of 1973 farm income, which helps to explain their focus on measurement problems. During the period 1960-1971 the changes in farm income were gradual and the revisions of the data pub- lished by USDA were relatively small. From 1972 to 1973 farm income in- creased nearly 78% and the subsequent July 1974 revisions of total net farm income and realized net farm income showed increases of 35% and 23% respectively. The revisions focused attention on the procedures used to estimate farm income. Many of the problems on which the Task Force fo- cused were caused by USDA's reliance on historical marketing patterns to allocate crop and livestock sales during the year. One Of the principal areas addressed by the 1975 Task Force was the integration of farm income data with the national income and product accounts. GNP and other summary measures provided by the national income and product accounts force a certain consistency in accounting among sec- tors and make farm income accounting potentially more difficult than would be the case if only agricultural sector uses were considered. The Task Force Report cites a U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau Of Economic Analysis study which showed that the quarterly estimates Of farm income had the largest revisions Of any income type in the national income and product accounts over the prior ten year period. The Task Force suggests lthat this may occur because unrealistic measures are used. An additional explanation not considered by the Task Force is that, since more data are available for the agricultural sector relative to other sectors, farm in- come might be subject to greater revisions than income in other sectors. Further, the greater inherent variability in farm income relative tO other 64 sectors would lead to greater expected revisions for the farm sector even if the measurement procedures were comparable among sectors. Farm inventory estimates also caused a problem with revisions even during the 19605. The importance of inventory estimates is magnified somewhat since the USDA estimate Of net change in farm inventories enters into the change in business inventories component Of GNP in the national income and product accounts on a quarterly basis. In order to be consis- tent with other sectors the farm sector also needs to account for inven- tories of purchased inputs and "work-in-progress." The Task Force then suggests that this latter component is probably not feasible to measure at this time, since weather and other factors can significantly affect growing crops. Thus, treating growing crops as work-in-progress may cause some difficulties. The separation of corporate income of farms is also difficult under the current system but is required in order to arrive at an accurate measure Of national income. The income of farm establishments owned by corporations in non-farm industries can be double counted in the current national income and product accounts. This also raises a question Of the need for disaggregated or distributional information on the claimants to income in the farm sector. Increases in corporate ownership are not well documented nor are other organizational or ownership pattern changes in the farm sector. Thus, little data exists on the distribution of income by the legal organization of farms. While suggesting that the proposed Census classification of primary, part-time and business associated farms would improve the data on farm income by giving estimates by organizational form, the Task Force avoids many Of the distributional questions by argu- ing that these are not in the scope of their study. 65 The recommendations of the 1975 Task Force were in four broad areas: accounting rules and definitions, baSic data, timing and revisions, and improved techniques for data use. Under accounting rules they suggest that the farm should be treated as a business establishment rather than a family or household and thus the term "net income of farms“ should be sub- stituted for "net income of farm operators." In addition to this they re- commend that economic activity in the farm sector be measured and empha- ‘ sized primarily as gross value addedl/ rather than net income of farms. This former concept is a more comprehensive one and includes the latter as a principal component and can be reasonably estimated with existing data. They also recommended that farm income be measured on an establish- ment basis in preference to a product basis,§/ but at the same time recog- nized the difficulty in develOping a precise definition of an establish- ment consistent with other sectors. A further examination of the estab- lishment concepts used in other sectors shows that these concepts are quite varied and even incompatible in aggregation. The differences arise primarily in the operationalization of the establishment concept, however, the vehicles used for data collection in other sectors also tend to aggra- vate these differences. Thus, the difficulty in precisely defining an establishment concept, noted by the Task Force, might have been due to the existing inconsistencies in the operationalized concepts used in other sectors. The Task Force also perceived a need for better data on industry I] See next section of this chapter for a definition of this concept. g/ Ibid. 66 size and specialization and hence argued for better measures of interfarm transactions with offsetting entries in cash receipts and production ex- penses to assure accurate net income estimates. ApprOpriate changes to separate capital formation on farms, paricularly own account capital for- mation, from current production were recommended. Specifically, removal of increases in beef breeding and dairy herds and laying flocks from in- ventory change was recommended along with the inclusion of depreciation on own account capital in the production expenses. The Task Force also recommended that the treatment of CCC loans be changed to include crops under loan as farmer owned inventories rather than sales unless the far- mer forfeits the collateral for the CCC loan. The current practice treats CCC loans as sales at the time the loan is made and appropriate adjust- ments are made when CCC loans are redeemed. The current practice was probably more apprOpriate during the period of the 19305 through the 19605 when chronic surpluses dominated in the farm sector. The establishment of farmer held grain reserves under the Food and Agriculture Act of 1977 also gives added significance to the Task Force recommendation. Consistent with the stated earlier recommendations of this Task Force, they also recommend that inventories of purchased inputs be mea- sured so that current and suggested income measures more accurately re- flect income from current production. They further suggest that the gross rental value of farm dwellings and associated production expenses 'be included in the real estate industry rather than farming industry. The net rental income of nonoperator landlords is excluded from farm in- come but to be consistent with the gross value added on farms concepts, this should be included along with appropriate depreciation, indirect taxes and interest payments of nonoperater landlords. The final 67 recommendation concerning accounting rules and definitions follows Grove's recommendation that "realized net farm income" be dropped as a separate series. In the area of basic data the Task Force recommended that better quarterly data be collected on: 1) crop movements, 2) expenditures for feed and livestock, 3) inventories of cattle and calves, and 4) inventories of purchased inputs. The probability surveys of grain buyers now used by I ESCS: Statistics is a reSponse to this first request since it now provides .data on the movements of major grains within a month after the sales. At the time of the 1975 Task Force Report, data on crop movements often was not available until 18 months after the end of the calendar year. However, this does not help to measure interfarm sales nor does the probability survey cover all cr0ps, so the basic data in the area of crop movements still does not meet all of the recommendations. 0n the livestock side the Task Force noted the inadequacy of data on interstate movement of feeder and stocker cattle for which better data is needed for accurate farm income estimates. In line with their earlier recommendations on in- terfarm transactions, the Task Force recommended that investigations be made as to the feasibility of collecting such data for livestock. In the area of production expenses the recommendations centered around making better use of and increasing the sample size of the ESCS: Statistics Farm Production Expenditure Survey to obtain expense data by region and size and type of farm." Among particular expense items the need for quarterly data on feed, livestock and fertilizer was deemed most cri- tical because of the inherent variability in the purchases of these items by farmers during the course of a year. Since changes in inventories displayed the most need for revisions 68 in the past, this area was also cited as needing more and better primary data. Cattle and calf inventories, especially cause difficulties because of the failure to separate livestock on feed, which are really work-in- progress, and beef breeding and dairy herds which are actually capital items. Thus improved data of sufficient detail to separate out these aspects are needed. The absence of data on purchased inputs also prevents accurate income estimation on an accrual basis and this type of data is necessary to have accounts consistent with the national income and pro- duct accounts. The price data used in estimating farm income was judged adequate for the most part by the Task Force. Problems do occur when only season average prices are available for certain craps, especially when prices and sales are changing during the year. Contract prices where the terms of trade are unknown also cause some problems when these prices are used in estimating income. For income estimation the Task Force was particu- larly concerned with matching prices with quantities sold rather than the conceptual problems in discovering prices. This is in keeping with over- all concern of the Task Force with the estimation accuracy of revisions of the farm income data. The final two areas of recommendations concern the relationship of farm income work within the U.S. Department of Agriculture and between USDA and the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the Department of Com- merce. The constraints placed on USDA by BEA can lead to problems in the timing of revisions. For the purposes of this study the recommenda- tion for a higher priority for farm income work within the USDA particu- larly within ESCS: Economics is important. The implementation of many of the recommendations of the Task Force is impossible without increased 69 staff and budget resources. As in the earlier Task Force study the ques- tion of priorities among the recommendations is not well developed so that it is difficult to make improvements within an incremental budget process. Thus a study of the uses and users of the data seems necessary to a better understanding of the benefits of various improvements, so that some priorities can be set on implementation of the suggested changes. A point raised by Emanuel Melichar, concerning the recommendations of the Task Force to separate out the inventory change of beef breeding and dairy herds from inventories of current production, suggests that the overall impact of these data improvements might not be very significant in terms of the effect on total farm income. However he is quick to add that such an action is conceptually sound. This does suggest that in de- termining priorities among different types of changes in estimating pro- cedures or accounting rules, those which have the greatest effect on the aggregate income figures might be given priority. However one must also give consideration to the importance of individual components of the aggregate which often have separate uses. In the case of farm inventories it might be very important to have measures which are conceptually sound since these data also affect business inventories in the National Income and Product Accounts which have uses distinct from the aggregate farm in- come data. In general the motivation and recommendations of the 1975 Task 'Force on Farm Income are quite different from the 1972 Task Force. The more recent group was concerned with improving the preliminary farm income estimates each January and with the current quarterly farm income estimates. So in general the recommendations were not centered on conceptual issues but rather on the provision of key bits of data on a more timely basis in 70 order to improve accuracy and reduce revisions. 3.2.4. GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT DATA IMPROVEMENT PROJECT The Gross National Product Data Improvement Project was undertaken in 1973 by the Statistical Policy Division of the Office of Management and Budget (now the Office of Federal Statistical Policy and Standards in the U.S. Department of Commerce) to examine the accuracy and timeliness of the underlying data base of the National Accounts. This project ended in 1976 with their report following later. Chapter six of their final report is entitled “Improving Non-Benchmark Estimates: Farm Sector." They justi- fied this separate study on farming sector income even though gross farm product has traditionally been only about 4% of GNP. They cited four reasons for examing farm income data. First the volatility of farm out- put in the short run can greatly affect quarterly changes in overall na- tional output. Second, farming still is a major industry in the economy. Third, the importance of U.S. Farming in the world food economy has in- creased in recent years. Fourth, the current agricultural statistics show more clearly than other sector statistics the problems of obsoles- cence in the Federal statistical system arising from structural changes in an industry. 6 The concern of the GNP Data Improvement Project was almost exclu- sively on the current quarterly estimates of national income. In the farm 'sector accounts this concern was manifested by examining the data base for the current quarterly estimates of income originating in the farm sector and to a slightly lesser extent the January estimates of farm income. The quarterly farm inventory change data also received heavy emphasis. Given that the current methods used by USDA in estimating quarterly farm income 71 rely heavily on extrapolations of annual data and other historically based procedures, the GNP Data Improvement Project concentrated their recommendations on a shift away from the indirect data sources presently used to more directly reported figures. For the most part these recom- mendations paralleled those of the 1976 Task Force (this latter group in their report noted that their ideas were supplemented greatly through the help of the GNP Data Improvement Project). The 1975 Task Force placed a higher emphasis on the data problems associated with the January prelimi- nary farm income estimates as well as the subsequent July revisions but their recommendations were still reasonably congruent with the GNP project. The GNP project's recommendations also focused somewhat more on the Bureau of Economic Analysis data on gross farm product and income originating in farming than on the USDA's farm income estimates. This is not as serious a difference as it appears, since most of their recommendations also in- fluence USDA in that USDA is the main data provider for BEA regarding quarterly farm income. One of the spinoff benefits of the GNP project's work is that they documented the procedures currently used by USDA in making the quarterly estimates of farm income. Most of the methodology that USDA uses in esti- mating farm income is only published for the annual July estimates with little information on how quarterly or preliminary estimates are made. Hence this study of the GNP Data Improvement Project is an important con— ‘ tribution in this area. 3.2.5. GUEBERT In a paper presented at the WorkshOp on Farm Sector Financial Accounts in April 1977, Steven Guebert reviewed some of the data and 72 concepts used in the farm income accounts as well as identifying some of the major users and uses of the farm income data. Guebert notes that the farm income data enter into the deliberations on national level farm poli- cy and he considers this one of the major uses of the data. There is also a program implementation use for the data in that the state estimates of farm income enter into the revenue sharing allocation mechanisms. At the state level he suggests that government budget planning is an important use. Guebert also noted that private sector uses of the aggregate farm income data lie in three major areas. First, U.S. farm income data are used in advertising and investment decisions in what can be called the farm input sector, e.g., machinery manufacturers, fertilizer supplying firms as well as those firms which supply inputs to these firms. Second, the local and national political interest groups concerned with agricul- ture use the data. Third, the banking and financing industry is a user of farm income data. Guebert then makes the statement that the primary interest of the private sector appears to be more with the overall eco- nomic activity or total dollar turnover for specific commodities or ex- pense area rather than net income per se. For the most part the percep- tions of the author were not substantiated by any study of users and uses. In evaluating the data base used in estimating farm income, Guebert considers the measurement of quantities of inputs as the major data constraint to better farm income estimates. The second data base problem is in the area of timeliness of the marketing data for cash re- ceipts estimates. A third area of difficulty is in the determination of farmer owned inventories and inventory change. In this case the problem centers on substituting the value of the change in on-farm stocks for the value of the change in farmer owned stocks. The former neglects farmer 73 owned inventories held in elevators or other facilities off the farm. In addition to the conceptual problem concerning the inclusion of breeding livestock as part of current inventory Guebert notes that a further data problem arises from measuring inventory change as the value of the change in the number of head of livestock. For current production this method neglects the change in weight of the national livestock herd. Guebert appears to overstate his case in this area since it is the value of the inventory change that is used in the national accounts not the physical change. So as long as the weight of the animals is discounted in the pricing system, measuring value on a per head basis would not seem to be a significant problem. Also as long as beef breeding and dairy livestock are included in the inventory account, valuing inventory change on a per head basis is probably not that serious a problem. Guebert also raises some questions as to the apparent difficulty of reconciling the USDA farm income accounts to national income and pro- duct accounts of the Department of Commerce. This was a major concern of the two Task Forces on farm income and the GNP Data Improvement Project. Guebert argues that the problem is not one of estimation but that dif- ferences only arise in the manner of presentation. He goes further to state that the concepts used by USDA in the farm income accounts fits more closely the data needs of the Department of Commerce than the data from any other sector. Guebert's analysis while not as detailed as some of the earlier projects and Task Force reports raises a number of important issues. By identifying user and uses the seeds are sown for a better understanding of the needs and design of the system. Given the nature of his study, Guebert cannot really be blamed for not making the explicit connection 74 between uses and redesign of farm income data system. His approach at least reflects a concern for these issues. Guebert's findings also raise a question as to the significance of the alleged problems associated with bringing the farm income accounts more in line with the national income and product accounts. If the USDA data fit the needs of the Department of Commerce as well as any other sector then improving the data for the national income and product accounts should probably be given a lower priority than was suggested in some of the earlier studies. 3.2.6 AGRICULTURAL AND RURAL DATA WORKSHOP Lee Bawden, £3, 31,, presented a paper at the AAEA-USDA Agricul- tural and Rural Data WorkshOp which analyzed the USDA farm income data from a slightly different perspective than some of the earlier studies. Their main concern was with measuring the well being of farm operator families so they concentrated on the areas of personal income and wealth of farm people. Their findings were that the existing farm incOme and wealth data were inadequate to measure the well being of farm pe0ple. The differences here come about primarily because of problems in defining the farm papulation and in the treatment of capital gains. The concern of Bawden, 33, 21,, with farm families as opposed to farm businesses is somewhat different than the studies summarized earlier. They state that the agricultural community seems to prefer a farm operator family concept as the appropriate unit of observation but it is unclear on what grounds this statement is based. One aspect that they point out but do not develop to any extent is the need for distributional data on farm income and wealth in order to understand the well being of farmers and to measure the impact of 75 government policy. Some types of distributions suggested include those by size and type of farm, time spent farming, tenure, age, net income, education and geographic region. They note that the current series on the personal income of the farm papulation does not allow one to evaluate the impact of government farm policies because the "farm population" in- cludes farm residents whose only ties to the sector are as a place to live and excludes farm operators who happen to live off the farm. Bawden, g1, 31,, suggest that distributional data which allow one to examine the impact of policies are needed to understand how the change in income brought on by policy changes affects agriculture. As with the earlier studies, this group seems implicitly to assume an unlimited budget in that they accept the recommendations of the earlier Task Forces and recommend that their findings be implemented in addition to the earlier recommendations. They fail to identify the users and uses of this data so that some notion of the priorities for these improvements can be established nor do they give any other criteria for determing the importance of their suggested changes. 3.3 ALTERNATIVE CONCEPTUALIZATIONS Many of the studies summarized in the previous section suggested alternative accounting systems for farm income. This section will pre- sent the concepts of the farming sector currently used by USDA and some alternative conceptualizations of income and economic well being put forth in the literature. These alternative conceptualizations provide the basis for some of the recommendations of the final chapter of this study in that the results help to establish priorities in choosing between these con- cepts. 76 3.3.1 NATIONAL FAMILY FARM CONCEPT The current farm sector accounting system used by the U.S. Depart- ment of Agriculture treats the sector as if it were a single national family farm. Thus, the measure of income derived using this concept in- cludes the value of farm products consumed in farm households, government payments or transfers to farmers, and the imputed value of farm dwellings in addition to the cash receipts from the sales of farm products. This concept also implies that net returns to nonoperator landlords be excluded from farm income so this is included on the production eXpense side. The other expenses include depreciation, taxes, and interest on farm mortgages in addition to the current operating expenses. So in effect, this con- cept of the farming sector produces an accounting system similar to that used by a typical farm operator for Federal income tax purposes (Carlin and Smith, p. 2). This tax accounting analogy can be carried somewhat further in that the farm income accounts under this concept are on a cash accounting basis as are most individual farm tax returns rather than an accrual basis. The inclusion of inventory change in the total net farm income series is a departure from this cash accounting basis, but even this de- parture is not complete since inventories of purchased inputs are not deducted from the measured operating expenses. In estimating income using this national family farm concept, as with any concept of the sector, it is critical that the production ex- penses and income sides be comparable. Expenses must only be associated with the income generating activities included on the gross income side, e.g., if government payments to farmers are included on the income side then costs to farmers associated with program compliance should be 77 included on the expense side or if own account production of capital items is excluded from the income side then the associated production expenses should be excluded (Weeks, 1972). 3.2.2 ESTABLISHMENT CONCEPT This characterization of the farm sector views it as one made up of farm establishments. An industry, such as farming, is made up of those establishments for which more than half of their production is of the commodities characteristic to the industry. Establishments for which the production of agricultural commodities is their major activi- ty would be considered farm establishments. Thomas Carlin and Allen Smith provide a more general definition of an establishment as it is used in the national accounts and other Federal statistics. "An establishment is defined as an economic unit, generally at a single physical location, where business is conducted or where services or industrial operations are performed. Nhere distinct and separate economic activities are performed at a single physical location, each activity should be -treated as a separate establishment wherever: 1) no one in- dustry description in the classification includes such com- bined activities, 2) the emplo ent in each such economic activity is significant, and 3 reports can be prepared on the number of employees, their wages and salaries, sales or receipts, and other establishment type data. Establishments are the basic unit of account. Firms would be composed of one or more establishments." (p. 4) In many ways this establishment view of the farm sector is si- milar to the national family farm concept, since most family farms are probably each a separate establishment. However, this specific defini- tion of an establishment does not coincide on a one to one basis with the definitions used in arriving at the existing farm income accounts. The establishment view of the farm sector makes it clear that a fanm 78 can use its resources to produce both characteristic farm products, (e.g., cattle, corn) and ancillary products which are nonagricultural (e.g., trucking). Thus, in measuring income using this concept one would wish to determine all outputs of farms including those minor out- puts not normally considered as farm output in addition to the associ- ated production expenses for both the agricultural and nonagricultural products. This view of the farming sector would be more useful in an- swering questions of decision makers concerning the performance and eco- nomic behavior of farms, farm business-household relationships, the structure and control of the industry, and would make comparisons with other industries easier because data for these are also estimated on an establishment basis (Weeks, gt,.31., 1972). As was noted earlier these comparisons may be difficult because of the heterogeneity in the Opera- tionalization of the establishment concept in other industries. 3.2.3 PRODUCT CONCEPT Another characterization of the farm sector suggested by the 1972 Farm Income and Capital Accounting Task Force is a product concept. This concept implicitly recognizes that agricultural commodities are in some cases produced by establishments which do not produce characteristic farm products as a major activity. Thus, if one is interested in the output of all agricultural commodities then a product concept is needed to in- sure the consideration of farm products produced by both farm and non- farm establishments. On the output side of the production account only the output of characteristic agricultural products would be measured. But at the same time only those inputs associated with the production of these 79 characteristic products would be deducted in arriving at a net income estimate. This concept then would be particularly useful in assessing. the relationships between the total output of food and fiber commodities with the inputs used to produce them. Information concerning the pro- ductivity of the sector can also be derived more readily from data based on a product concept when compared to data with alternative con- ceptualizations. Other questions relating to aggregate supply of farm products are in most instances better approached with data organized on a product basis than on an establishment basis. The existing farm income accounts rely quite heavily on data which are closely related to this product concept, especially on the output side. Cash receipts for farm marketings are for all farm products and do not exclude production from non-farm establishments. However, on the input side the existing methodology uses data more closely akin to data collected on an establishment basis since it is impossible to sepa- ‘rate out those production expenses used in the production of ancillary products on farms. Thus, the empirical problem associated with using these alternative conceptualizations would be difficult to overcome un- less the existing data base were greatly modified. 3.3.4 VALUE ADDED CONCEPTS The production or value added approach to measuring income and product by industry is perhaps the most basic approach to national ac- counting in that it considers aggregate production as the sum of the pro- duction statements of the producing units in the economy (Kendrick, p. 39). Conceptually, value added can be estimated in two ways for a par- ticular sector. Using what is called a production approach, value added 80 for a sector is determined by taking the value of total production in the sector and deducting from this the cost of the intermediate products used in the production of the sector's current output. The second ap- proach is called the income approach. Value added for a sector, using the income approach, is estimated by summing the factor and nonfactor costs used in production. Factor costs include such items as labor com- pensation, net interest, and corporate profits while nonfactor charges might include depreciation and indirect business taxes. Value added for a sector should be identical no matter which ap- proach is used. The production approach is preferred when one wishes to deflate industry output to obtain a measure of real output. This ap- proach also provides a beginning point for the development of the input- output matrix for the economy. The income approach provides a statisti- cal check and allows for the analysis of factor shares by industry in addition to making it possible to deflate to obtain real factor cost (Kendrick, p. 40). For agriculture the value added concept is the desired concept 'of the Department of Commerce which they use in their estimates of farm output, gross product, and income published in the Survey of Current Business. However, in practice the value added concepts are modified somewhat by the Commerce Department in estimating the farm income and product accounts. Theoretically, at least, one should begin estimating the value added in farming using the production approach by estimating the value of production. Assuming that all production is sold, the value of produc- tion would equal the value of sales plus inventory change. But in agri- culture many farm products are not sold, instead these are used as in- termediate products on the same farm where produced. For example, feed grains are often fed to cattle on the same farm where produced. The 81 estimation of value of production as the value of sales plus inventory change is the basis for the existing U.S. Department of Commerce esti- mates of farm product. This underestimates the value of production by the amount of unsold or own account production in the sector. Simunek ‘notes that the value of sales is apprOpriate for cash income analysis, but also points out that a measure of value of production which includes own account production is necessary to avoid distortions in productivity analysis, input—output studies, size and type of farm classifications, and estimates of total capital formation. Thus, it appears Simunek is arguing that while the value added concept might be appropriate for cer- tain uses, the current definition of farm output is an inadequate opera- tionalization of this concept because it neglects own account uses. Gross farm product is used by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the U.S. Department of Commerce as the estimate of value added in farming. The current measure using the production approach starts with farm output. As noted above, farm output is not really the total value of production in farming; rather it is the sum of cash receipts from farm marketings and CCC loans, other farm income, farm products con- sumed on farms, change in farm inventories, and gross rental value of farm dwellings. From farm output the value of intermediate goods and services consumed is deducted. This latter item includes net rent paid to nonoperator landlords as part of the intermediate goods and service. Gross farm product is the measure of value added in farming since in theory at least it is an attempt to measure total value of production less intermediate purchases. It should be noted that BEA also adjusts the gross farm product figure by adding adjustments for such items as wage supplements, social security contributions from wages and salaries, interest received and Federal fines. 82 Using the income approach, gross farm product is the sum of the factor and nonfactor costs, i.e., net interest, corporate profits, pro- prietor's income, employee compensation, indirect business taxes, cap- ital consumption less direct government subsidies to operator landlords. This differs from the USDA definition of net farm income which includes proprietor's net income, corporate profits and direct government sub- sidies (GNP Data Improvement Project). National income originating in farming is also derived in the BEA estimates. For the economy as a whole, national income is derived in theory by subtracting depreciation and indirect business taxes from gross national product (Schultze, p. 45). National income originating in farming is derived in a similar manner. Gross farm product less capital consumption allowances and indirect business taxes plus subsi- dies to operator landlords equals national income originating in farm- ing using the existing BEA accounts. National income originating in farming can also be estimated by summing net interest, corporate pro- fits, proprietors' income and employee compensation. The 1975 Task Force on Farm Income recommended that USDA use the value added approach in estimating and presenting data on farm income. They noted that the gross farm product and income originating in farm- ing could be approximatedby merely changing the accounting rules now used in estimating farm income so that a change in the accounting sys- tem is not necessary. Since they also recommend an accounting for all output, their recommendations would require collecting new data on own account uses of production and on some interfarm sales which are now excluded. Therefore, changing the accounting rules would in effect require more primary data than is now available. 83 3.3.5 TAXFILERS INCOME CONCEPT Periodically the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) publishes data on income obtained from samples of individual and business income tax returns. The concept of income used by IRS is sufficiently different from the USDA income concept so that the two concepts are not readily comparable. Edward Reinsel has noted several differences between the farm in- come concept of IRS and USDA. On the gross receipts side he found that the IRS and USDA estimates were reconciled fairly easily. The IRS figures include intrastate livestock sales to other farmers which are netted out of the USDA estimates. The IRS estimates exclude some sales of breeding livestock which are treated as capital assets, however USDA includes these as receipts for livestock. In the IRS data a significant amount of farm income is not measured because crop share tenants report only their own share of the farm receipts while the landlord might report income from the farm operation as rent rather than farm receipts. Since the prices (used to estimate farm income by USDA include normal marketing charges, the gross receipts data of USDA would then be higher than the IRS estimates of gross receipts,'ceteris paribus, in that receipts are reported to IRS without these marketing charges. Since the USDA subtracts out these charges on the production expense side, the net income estimates should not differ dramatically because of this. IRS data also exclude some receipts from corporations that are primarily non-farm businesses. How- ever, IRS data also include some corporate receipts from foreign countries. The sum total of these conceptual and definitional differences on the gross receipts side appear offsetting since gross receipts on tax returns and from USDA estimates were about the same in 1962 as noted by Reinsel. Data for 1974 suggests that this same relationship holds. 84 When comparing USDA net farm income with IRS net farm profits there are large differences in the reported data. Since the gross income estimates are basically the same, this suggests that the major conceptual differences exist in expense accounting between the two data suppliers. For instance, depreciation in the USDA accounts is estimated at replace- ment cost while IRS data can be based on the book value of the assets and IRS considers gross rent as an expense while USDA only uses net rent to nonoperator landlords as an expense because of USDA's desire to measure income based on a national family farm concept. 3.3.6 COMBINING INCOME AND WEALTH Income is often used by economists and public decision makers as a proxy measure of well being in society. Burton Weisbrod and Lee Hansen have developed an approach that, while not a perfect measure of current welfare, attempts to go beyond traditional income measures as indicators of well being. Their suggested measure is a combination of current in- come plus current net worth. Net worth is converted to an annuity to overcome the difficulties of combining a stock concept like net worth with a flow concept such as income. By adding the annual lifetime annuity va- lue of current net worth to current income Weisbrod and Hansen develop a measure of welfare that can be used to assess the economic position of various sectors of society. Thomas Carlin and Edward Reinsel used the methodology developed by Weisbrod and Hansen to compare the economic position of farmers with other sectors and the economic well being among different units within the farm sector. Their results show that when wealth is added to income, the distribution of well being in the farm sector became more equal than 85 when income alone was considered. Weisbrod and Hansen's findings for the entire U.S. economy showed well being to be more unequally distributed when wealth is added. 50 the apparent disparity in welfare between the farm and non-farm sectors when income alone is considered is less pro- nounced when wealth is also considered. This points out some of the difficulties in using farm income as a measure of well being for the farming sector. Not only does it neglect the distribution of income within the sector but important wealth effects fail to receive proper attention. 3.3.7 PARITY RETURNS CONCEPT The concept of parity returns was first put forth in a 1967 USDA report to the U.S. Congress concerning parity income, in reSponse to a mandate for this type of study set out in the Food and Agriculture Act of 1965. The concept of parity returns was used in place Of the parity in- come concept laid out in legislation in the 19305 and 40s. Parity income is defined in the 1936 and 1938 agriculture legislation and is in terms of the historical ratio, using a 1910-1914 base, between per capita in- come of the farm and non-farm population. The 1948 definition of parity income eliminates the fixed base period and attempts to establish an equi- valent standard of living between the farm and non-farm sectors using a moving average of the 10 preceding years. These parity income concepts have some obvious limitations such as reliance on a fixed base, the ex- clusion of off farm income of farm operators, and the reliance on averages of all farmers which neglects important distributional effects by size and type of farm. To overcome some of the disadvantages of the parity income 86 concept the USDA report developed an income concept called parity returns. Parity returns are defined as "income required to make the current rate of return to the labor, capital and management employed in farm production equal to the current rate of return to comparable resources employed in other sectors of the economy." (USDA, 1967, p. 9) In operationalizing this concept both the income and changes in net worth of farmers are com- pared to the opportunity cost in nonagriculture uses of the resources currently used by farmers. The approach also took into account distribu- tional differences by size and type of farm and did not rely solely on averages as did earlier parity income measures. Parity returns standards were developed for capital and labor in farming which in theory reflects the returns to farm capital and labor in comparable nonagricultural uses. So in effect these returns exclude off farm income of farmers. Another limitation of the concept is that the in- clusion of capital gains might not be appropriate for short run compari- sons when farm capital would tend to be illiquid and thus spending from net worth to increase well being might not be an available option. Two aspects of the parity returns study are important in the con- text of this analysis. First, the idea of separating out returns to vari- ous resources used in farming provides useful information for agricultural policy decisions, e.g., in choosing between programs for improving agri- cultural credit and programs aimed at giving tax relief to farmers. Secondly, this study showed the importance of considering the income and returns position of farmers by size and type of farm. The finding of the USDA on parity returns showed that farmers with gross sales over $20,000 were earning parity returns or more in 1966 under each alternative method of calculation used while farmers under $20,000 gross sales earned less 87 than parity returns under all methods. The smallest farmers (under $5,000 gross sales) earned only one third to two fifths of parity returns in 1966 (USDA 1976, p. IV). 50 the average income figures even for a relatively good year like 1966 fail to show the important differences in income with- in the sector. 3.4 SUMMARY Six specific analyses of farm income data were summarized in the first major section of this chapter. Each of these point out some of the important shortcomings of the existing farm income data system but all differ in approach from this study. These earlier evaluations often be- gin to question the conceptual relevance of the USDA farm income data and all make recommendations for improvements in the data. However in all but one case they fail to identify the users and uses of the farm income data. For the most part assumptions are implicitly or explicitly made about the uses of the data without any attempt to substantiate the con- gruence of these assumptions with reality. This failure to consider the uses of the data in decision making makes it difficult to place any weights on their recommendations or to establish priorities for improve- ments. The consideration of users and uses is not the only means of set- ting priorities but_the literature summarized provided few other criteria for determining the significance of the recommended improvements. These studies of farm income as well as other research provide a set of alternative conceptualizations of farm income or well being which are also summarized in this chapter. These include: 1) the national family farm concept, 2) an establishment concept of the farming sector, 3) a product concept of farming, 4) value added concepts of sector income, 88 5) taxfilers income, 6) a concept combining income and wealth, 7) a con- cept of parity returns. The results presented in later chapters will be used to show the strengths and weaknesses of these alternative concepts as bases for the information to be used in decision making concerning farm income. CHAPTER 4 DESCRIPTIVE RESULTS: THE FARM INCOME INFORMATION SYSTEM 4.1 INTRODUCTION This chapter presents a description of the existing farm income information system. A complete description of this information system does not now exist anywhere in the literature. The information systems paradigm developed in Chapter 2 provides a convenient framework for under- standing and analyzing the farm income information system and as such will be the basis for organizing the overview and summary presentations in this chapter. A descriptive examination of the users and uses of the USDA will also be presented. This latter section is based on the results of a mail questionnaire sent to a random sample drawn from the mailing list of the USDA statistical bulletin Farm Income Statistics with foreign addresses and libraries eliminated. In addition some of the more detailed observa- tions with regard to data uses by some public and private users are de- veloped from personal interviews. Thirty-five of these interviews were with peOple in different roles in all the organizations that normally par- ticipate in public policy decisions for agriculture. Ten others were follow up interviews with individuals on the Farm Income Statistics mail- ing list. Finally the relevant parts of the primary data used in the USDA farm income estimates will also be described based on written docu- mentation and personal interviews with the providers of the data. 89 90 4.2 OVERVIEW It is difficult to separate a discussion of the uses of farm in- come data from a description of the farm income information system. In describing the components of the system it is necessary to start by con- sidering the ultimate decisions that must be made and work back to the data sources used to estimate farm income. The farm income information system as perceived in this research has four basic components: a pri- mary data subsystem, a formatting and communication subsystem, an analy- sis subsystem and finally a decision making subsystem. Figure 4-1 sche- matically outlines these components. The distinctions between these parts are not as clear as the titles would imply but this categorization does allow one to focus on the most important interralationships in the system. When comparing the existing farm income information system with the idealized system outlined in Chapter 2, one finds many similarities. This paradigm pinpoints five basic steps or actions that make up an infor- mation system, beginning with theoretical concepts and ending in decision making. The farm income information system begins with a theoretical con- cept of farm income. The basis of this concept is developed in section 3.3.1 and revolves around what is called the national family farm concept. The operationalization of this concept of farm income involves defining a set of accounting rules or relationships which relate various price and quantity data, yielding farm income as a residual. Thus, the Operation- alization phase actually involves the conceptualization, operationaliza- tion and measurement of the different sets of primary data needed. The primary data underlying the farm income series are provided by a number of government and private sources, such as the Statistics Branch of the Economics, Statistics, and Cooperatives Service (ESCS) in USDA, the 91 AN IDEALIZED AGRICULTURAL COMPONENTS OF THE USDA FARM INFORMATION SYSTEM INCOME INFORMATION SYSTEM Decision Making Decision Making Subsystem I Information for Decision Makers Farm Income Information for Decision Makers I [ Interpretation and Analysis I l Analysis Subsystem ] i % i W /A W/ % MeQSUrement I Comunicatl' on and Formatting Subsystem .L Measurement 7 Operationalization Of PrImary Data of the Operationalization Operationalization of Concepts Farm Income of Primary Data Concept Concepts Primary Data Concepts Primary Data Subsystem A [ Theoretical Concepts I I Concept of Farm Income I Reality FIGURE 4-1 COMPARISON OF AN IDEALIZED AND OPERATING INFORMATION SYSTEM 92 Bureau of Census in the U.S. Department of Commerce, the Farm Equipment Institute, and the Market News Branch of the Agricultural Marketing Ser- vice in USDA. These, among other, government and private data sources make up what can be called the primary data subsystem. Since'farm income is calculated as a residual, the measurement phase of the idealized information system becomes more of a formatting process when applied to the farm income data system. In cases where de- cision making is not tied organizationally to the data system the communi- cation between those who produce the data and the ultimate decision makers is important. With respect to the farm income infonnation system these formatting and communication functions are performed primarily by the Farm Income Unit in ESCS and to a lesser extent by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the U.S. Department of Commerce. In addition to these government agencies, a communication function is also performed by edu- cational institutions, private publishers of agricultural and trade maga- zines and other government agencies. These organizations constitute what can be called the formatting and communication subsystem of the farm in- come information system. The analysis and decision making phases of the farm income informa- tion system are at least conceptually the same as in the idealized system. However, the diverse nature and number of decision makers and analysts dictates that these phases be viewed as subsystems rather than merely steps in a process. The analysts include government agencies, private consultants, educational institutions and the staffs of the primary deci- sion makers intereSted in farm income. Decision makers are in both the public and private sectors and make decisions with regard to public poli- cy, demand estimation, credit needs and other areas. 93 4.3 USERS AND USES Government data and information systems often begin with one type of ultimate use or decision as a primary focus. However, even in those cases where data are collected strictly for administrative purposes, mul- tiple uses for government provided data usually develOp despite the ori- ginal intent and design of the data. Farm income data are no exception to this. Through time a number of different uses of this data have de- veloped both in the public and private sectors. This section will attempt 'to identify the various user groups associated with the farm income data and to categorize the various uses of the data. 4.3.1 LIMITATIONS 0F MAIL SURVEY POPULATION Before proceeding into a discussion of the results of the ques- tionnaire a few statements on the survey design would seem appropriate._ This should reveal some of the limitations of the results with regard to identification of the relevant p0pulation. Farm income information like other types of information possesses attributes of high fixed costs of collection relative to the costs of transmission of the data to additional users. Therefore, one would ex- pect many individuals to obtain the farm income data from sources other than the original supplier, in this case from sources other than the bul- letin Farm IncOme StatiStics each year from the U.S. Department of Agri- culture. Thus the population by definition excludes those users of USDA farm income data who receive it from other sources. Even within the De- partment of Agriculture these data are supplied to other individuals through the Agricultural Outlook publication, various press releases, and other sources such as the annual volume, Agricultural Statistics, and 94 extension service reports. In the private sector sources such as maga- zines, newspapers, trade publications, radio, television, libraries, and private consultants report USDA farm income statistics. The existence of multiple sources of USDA farm income data creates some difficulties in using the results of a sample drawn from the mailing list provided by USDA. Very little can be said about the overall magni- tude of the use of farm income based on this survey since many users are probably excluded from the population. However, as long as those who are on the mailing list are fairly representative of the entire population of users, one can use the survey to gain an understanding of the various types of users and uses of the farm income data. If the assumption is made that the total number of different types of users is directly propor- tional to the number of the types of users found on the mailing list then one can begin to obtain an indication of the relative importance between different users and uses when measured in terms of absolute frequency of use. A comparison of numbers of users and uses based on the mail sam- ple does not take into account the importance in terms of value or social welfare, etc., of any one type of use but instead treats all users and/or uses as of the same importance. This is an inherent difficulty in using random sampling; one must assume that those who are not selected are of equal importance to those selected in some respects. The relationship among economic structure, income distribution and the supply and demand for information developed in the conceptual framework for this study suggests that in some cases different types of users and uses should receive higher priority than others in the design of a_government information system. Others can undoubtably develoo 95 different criteria for determining the importance of various users and uses. Implied by this is that frequency of use is not necessarily a good proxy for the importance of a given use. So a mail survey also has some shortcomings in this respect. These problems in defining the p0pulation and in sampling begin to point out some of the limitations of this methodology for evaluating the farm income information system. However, it is not unreasonable to assume that those individuals who are the principal users of fanm income data are likely to be on the mailing list, especially those users outside of the Federal government, since the most detailed data on farm income are not readily available from the other sources. This assumption would not appear to hold in all cases within the Federal government where inter- nal lines of communication would probably transmit much of this informa- tion and direct distribution rather than mailing is more likely. Further- more, users of detailed data are more likely to understand the concepts and definitions and to be able to respond intelligently to alternatives. Casual users tend not to know the limits of the data. 4.3.2 SELECTION OF SAMPLE The total mailing list contained 4224 names and addresses, of these 268 were foreign addresses, and 290 were libraries or duplicates leaving a pOpulation of 3666 to be sampled. Libraries were removed from the population because the ultimate concern of this study was to obtain information about the use of the data in decision making. It was felt that libraries were not ultimate users of the data and therefore could be left out of the survey. Foreign organizations or individuals were also excluded since it was felt that input from these users was not relevant 96 for questions concerning the apprOpriate design of a United States farm income information system funded at least, in part through U.S. tax dol- lars. In selecting the apprOpriate sample size for the mail survey no clear cut method could be used without making some assumptions because of the multi-purpose nature of the questionnaire. As Moser and Kalton (p. 149) note there is "no perfect solution" to this difficulty. Thus, for this study it was assumed that the determination of the users and uses of the farm income data was the most important objective of the survey. From this an arbitrary decision concerning significant users and/or levels of use was made so a sample size could be ascertained. A priori, fourteen different user groups were tentatively identified. If all groups were equally represented in the pOpulation then 1/14 of the population would be in each group. This arbitrary proportion of 1/14 or .07 was used to provide a basis for selecting the sample size.’ A 1 to 2 percent error in this was deemed acceptable. Using standard methodsl/ this decision then led to a selection of a sample size of 268. A 50 percent response rate was also assumed so the actual sample size was doubled and then rounded up to 545. These 545 names and addresses were selected at random from the USDA mailing list. 1/ Where n is sample size, p is proportion of p0pulation in a user group and S.E. is the standard error, then without the finite p0pulation cor- rection ’ _ Egl-p). " ' S.E. For this study p=.O7 and S.E.=.015, so n=290. Using the finite population correction of n' = _B_.where N is the population size, 3666, n' is 268. 1+9 97 4.3.3 MAIL SURVEY RESULTS Of the 545 samples, some form of response was obtained from 307 individuals. These responses are characterized in part in Table 4-1. A total of 270 questionnaires had responses to the questions concerning the use of farm income data. These provide the primary basis for the descriptive results which follow. TABLE 4-1 MAIL SURVEY CHARACTERISTICS Total USDA Mailing List 4224 Foreign Addresses 268 Libraries and Duplicates 290 Population for Survey 3666 Sample Size 645 Total Responses 308 Problem Responses: Bad Address 2 Library Foreign Institution Refused to Answer \OWOON Usable Responses 270 Usable Sample* 517 Response Rate} 52.22% *Sample size less bad addresses, libraries, and foreign institutions. The information systems paradigm used in this research provides a a guide for analyzing the farm income information system. The impor- tance of decision making in this paradigm stresses the need to identi- fy users and uses of information in order to evaluate the system. Table 4-2 presents data on the frequencies of different types of users obtained from the mail survey. The fourteen different user groups 98 identified prior to sampling seemed to be an adequate categorization of the users since less than 2 percent of the respondents and users were placed in the miscellaneous category. Perhaps the most significant fact to be gleaned from Table 4-2 is the comparison of respondents to users. While there were 270 usable reSponses to the mail survey, only 205 of these respondents actually made use of the farm income data provided by USDA. In three categories the rate of nonuse of the respondents seems worth noting. Only 53 percent of the farmers or ranchers who responded to the survey actually used the data. For commodity trading firms and farm product processing firms the rates of use among respondents were 50 and 43 percent, respectively. On the other side of the coin, all 23 farm input supply firms reported using the data. The rate of data use of re- spondents from most other major user catergories varied between 70 and 90 percent. In terms of the number of individuals in a user group, four major users of USDA farm income data are apparent. In order of number of users reported from the sample, educational institutions, the Federal government, farm input supplying firms, and banking and financing firms are the most prevalent users, each with greater than 10 percent of the sample. Educa- tional institutions made up 26.3 percent of the reported users of the farm income data. The relative importance of educational institutions as users is somewhat surprising but included in this total are state and county extension service personnel which accounted for 35 percent of the uSers within the educational institution category. If these extension service personnel were included as part of state and local government then this category would contain over 15 percent of the users. However, it was felt that the extension personnel, especially those at the state 99 ~.eN mo o.ooH mON o.oo~ oNN 4wca H.3H a m.m m m.m m asocm umdedue_ Fecsspsuwca< o o o.N e m.~ w .m>wpmcmaooo chaapzuwcm< e.aN m m.m NH m.o NH newscgm>om Page, Lo mpeum H.~N m m.e~ om H.eH mm newsccm>om poemuwu o.NH m N.o~ NN m.m mN me_ueeepc Le mewxeam ~.Nm e m.~ m o.N N meP._em Le \ucm mcpmmmuoca auscoca scam o o N.HH mN m.m mN manger scc$ merapqq=m\mcwcauumw=:mz H.N¢ m ¢.¢ m m.m NH coumcmao gucmc co Scum mpcmucogmmm Aucmugmav Mncmugmav yo ucmucmm zucmacmcm zucmaamcu aucmaamgu ocmzamgm accmacocu a m< muzpomn< m>wuapmm auspomn< m>pumpmm muapomn< xgommumu cam: mgwmacoz mgmmz mucmvcoammm >moamkm maum: oz< mhzmozommum ~i¢.m4m og—uwuu_u co.uua.umu xuppoa mcoguo a» :o—aaeLou=_ can: so: «zoocoppoum.x can; as season uppaaa cc mung pocmcoo om: Hut U Ne—gwkm um: >¢<:_¢N NN maum: No zc_hou m. o c c o o v o Nouoa so oumum NN.m o o c am.N o um.N o NNuo: o. o c c N c N c mzmz xv.o u_.— uN.o uN.c um._ No.o e um._ mucaupzmcou a. m N N m N o m ouo>_cm am.—N o um.. um.m uN.c o uN.o RN.N m:_o:N=_N Nm o m m. N a N N m:_xcam “4N. o o :5 2.2 o c N: 32.3. mm o o N aN o o N u=a=_ scam “N: o :6 "Nd a... 3N nmN um; 22.538 cc o p N m —N m m potato; u—.oN u_.— nN.c «N.c se.. u¢.m u¢.N— u¢.o cawuau_um:_ Nm N N N e N. mm mp NagoNNNust someone .ouoN mum: co.un=_o> mcpucacpm :oNNNENNNN ao._om meoguo o» :oNNascoN:_ cum: soc maoocappoumvz tau; NNuacu teases u.Nn=m cc mmam —oco=ou um: mum: 44¢ >N mzuma mo zo_p<4=N< mun—u mm_om No mapu> an acouaconc ELNN so mamcoaxu :o_au:vcca use «sous. scum mac—u mopam No mapo> an ace oucaom cones an x—NENN gauacoao Ego» can esou=N mucosxaa acoscco>cc «Noun an mmmcmaxo :oNNuauoga Esau mmapu mopam No cape) N: macaw No coasaz oc_asnm seem mcouacoqo scam No oeouc. gmnu uwz cc.uae:mcou _aa_aau gonna use copuo—uocaov scam acosumm>=p an: new mmcau.u=aaxm poo—qnu «mega scam menu. pea—auu ELNN No :oNNNcmao ecu aspen»: some. Esau vac—g so» mmmcoaxw nonconxo mcpuucoao scam Newscau mmmcoaxo :o_uu:eocq scam mance. ELNN Leguo use am:o5-:oz co—uopaaoa Esau Na venue. uu_aau can :opuo_:aoa grow we «saucy —a:cmcoa «panacea—u ago «save. Nucomcom acoN can usage. umuco>o wee mace» No guess: capuassmcou was: we mapa> gazes an maa.cuog gmuu NJNeossou an munvuuoc zmuu «Noam an mun—mums smug «Noam an wanes? Esau osoocw scam no: page» Noacc< venue. Esau an: ego mmocm eNNNNNuc Noacc< mcougoac an usage. scam am: as. mmoco Nucmugoav Nucousamv Nucuucomv Nucougumv cause usou:_ ago; on: we: on cazmc< oz sgzuc< «02 on «m: Nahum: Nagaucomv Nucoucomv pace»: apogoc »_uuacouoz Nauoma Ngo> Nassau so acagcnsou ~h<4u¢ mic m4m 35:8... 3282 o. . c N N N N N 2.3 eucougoa N.N N.N. N.NN N.N N.N. N.NN N.NN N:.u:N=.N .3533... 328.... N. . N e . N o N. .35. 38.5 aucmucog N.N N.N N.NN N.v. N... ..eo N.NN co.uoe.umu .3838... 33.32 ..N N N N . N N N. NN ness... eucmucme ..N ..N N.N N.N. ..N N.N. N.NN New: Noemaoocu o.:.cma< No N N e N N N .e Nu..oN u..a:N success; .... N.N. N.N N.N N.N. .... ..NN «ensue oN Nucmaaocu mu:.omn< am e N . . m e .N co mama cueoocoe ..NN N.N. ..N N.N. N.N. N.N. N.NN co.NNscoN=. 3:38.... 33.3.... N N N N N N N NN .828 macoucoqNoN mumauocom muceu.:mcou m:¢.uau..g=g cocoamzmz .occaac. co oc:N.:u.NN< am: 3.... M2. .55.. 32...... 3.... N. .23.. 38..-... . a N... . .22.... ass: N 2 on a on N a amouocou N N N m e N N . No magnom mm: >¢N mhm..N ..eeueee ..N N.N. N.N. N..N N.NN N.NN N.NN Ne.eeee.. Neeaseoe. N.N.NNNN NN N N N N N N N. Ne.NeeN ..eaucee N.N. N.N N.NN N.N. N.N N.NN N.NN N.NNNN Nucmaamcu mu:.oNa< NN c . N N N N N. Naac. scum ..eeueee ..N o o N.N o N.N. N.NN Neeeeceseu Necesaee. N.N.NNNN NN N c o . o N NN .NLNNNN .NeedeeN ..N. N... N.N N.N N.N. N.N. N.NN ee..=..NNe. Nucoacocm cu=.oNa< NN N N N N N N cc .NcoNNNuacN N cm :oamm N Nauugo a v56 N N am: N cog» NN=NN.:N=ou Nee—uuu..aaa .maoqmzmz .occouc. so aesuhwu.gm< xgwmwcm cease: No: on N Nuns... tem.. .N. .e.NNN eN=e=-e. ..NNN .N .N uNaumcoN N N N N N N N . Ne eueseN .NNNNNNN NNNN .N N.NNNNNN. Na NuaaoN ...-N N.NN. 121 categories. The low relative level of use of USDA forecasts found in this category seems to be attributable to the low level of use of fore- casts in general by this group since they have over twice the percen- tage of nonusers of forecasts compared to the other groups. When analyzing user categories and sources of forecasts the results tend to confirm the findings mentioned previously. In this case, the two major private sector farm income data users, farm input suppliers and banking and financing institutions, show the lowest level- of direct use of USDA forecasts and among the highest levels of use of both internal and private consultant forecasts. Two possible explana- tions for these phenomena are apparent. First, the importance of the decisions in these firms require multiple sources for validation and the reduction of uncertainty. Second, the ability of these firms to capture the returns to improved information causes these firms to be willing to make expenditures for more information. 4.3.4 NONRESPONDENTS In part, the applicability of the mail survey results to the entire population of farm income data users, or that part of the popu- lation on the USDA mailing list, depends upon whether and how the non- respondents to the survey differ from the respondents. Given the level of nonuse of the farm income data found among those who responded to the questionnaire, one reasonable hypothesis would be that those who did not respond to the questionnaire, for the most part, did not use the USDA farm income data. A counter hypothesis is that those who responded made up an inordinately large portion of the nonusers of the farm income data. This might be expected since it was more difficult to explain how 122 the data was used than to simply write that the data was not used. The responses to a telephone survey of the nonrespondents pre- sented in Table 4-12 seem to refute this latter hypothesis and support the hypothesis that those who did not respond also did not use the data. 0f the nonrespondents to the mail survey who were contacted, 56.7 per- cent said outright that they did not use the data while in another 13.3 percent of the cases, the individual to whom the mail survey was origi- nally sent was no longer with the firm or agency and the person con- ° tacted on the telephone could not refer the call to anyone who used the data. So almost 70 percent of those contacted did not use the data. This proportion is significantly different at the .01 level from the proportion of nonuse found among the respondents. Even the 56.7 percent level of nonuse is significantly different at the .01 level when com- pared to the 24.1 percent of nonuse found among the respondents.g/ Thus, if this percentage of nonuse is applied to 46.85 percent of the sample that did not respond and added to the 24.1 percent of the respon- dents who did not use the data then over 45 percent of the sample did not use the USDA farm income data. The fact that nearly half of those surveyed do not use the data is even more significant when one considers that the sample was drawn from a population that receive the data on a regular basis. Table 4-13 summarizes the breakdown of the nonrespondents by user category. While the sample size is relatively small, the nonre— spondents identified seem to be represented in about the same 2] The procedure for testing the difference between sample prOportions is presented in Freund, p. 285-287. 123 TABLE 4-12 NONRESPONDENT SURVEY RESULTS Adjusted Absolute Relative Relative Frequency Frequency Frequenc (Percent) (Percent{ Contacted ‘ 30 83.3 100.0 Use for general information 5 13.8 16.7 Use specifically 4 11.1 13.3 Do not use 17 47.2 56.7 No longer with firm or agency and could not refer to a user 4 11.1 13.3 Not Contacted 6 16.7 No telephone listing 4 11.1 Unpublished telephone 1 2.7 Unable to contact 1 2.7 Total Sample 36 100.0 Total Nonrespondents 237 TABLE 4-13 NONRESPDNDENTS BY USER CATEGORY Relative User Category Absolute Frequenc Frequency (Percent{ Educational Institution 4 13.3 Federal Government 6 20.0 Farm Input Supply 2 6.7 Banking or Financing 3 10.0 Private Consultants 2 6.7 News Media 1 3.3 State or Local Government 1 3.3 Miscellaneous 6 20.0 No User Group Given 5 16.7 Total Contacted 30 100.0 Unable to Contact 6 124 proportions as the respondents. Using a 2 test to test the differences between prOportions and the null hypothesis that the proportions of the contacted nonrespondents in each category are equal to the proportion of respondents in each category, at the 10 percent level the null hypo- thesis cannot be rejected for any category of user.§/ Thus, the nonre- spondents seem to be similar to the respondents in most ways except that the nonrespondents have a much lower level of use of the data than do the respondents. 4.3.5 IDENTIFICATION OF DECISION MAKERS TO BE INTERVIENED The main thrust of the personal interview portion of the re- search was aimed at the public policy uses of farm income data. A some- what more limited number of interviews with private sector data users were made to gain a better understanding of the uses of the farm income data in the farm input industry and the banking and financing industry. However the majority of those interviewed were in the agricultural poli- cy decision process at the national level. As was stated earlier, the value of information stems from the value of the decisions in which the information is used. Accepting the fact that some decisions are more significant than others forces one to have misgivings about relying on a random sample of users to set prior- ities on the redesign of a data system. The use of publically collected farm income data in public policy decisions was felt to be a major use, the importance and details of which would not be brought out in a _3/ Ibid. 125 strictly random sample of users. Given the papulation chosen for the mail survey, i.e., subscri- bers on a USDA mailing list, it appeared that public policy users might be underrepresented since more direct channels for supplying this in- formation exist for public policy decision makers when compared to the use of a mailed printed bulletin. Thus, the population was expanded to include more of these users. In a sense the total population of farm income data users was stratified with the major public policy decision makers being sampled at nearly a 100 percent rate while other users were sampled at a lower rate. The basis for selecting the public poli- cy users is outlined below. Through time the decision process in agricultural policy has ex- panded to include more actors than the traditional "Farm Bloc" of the 19205. The increased specialization of production in farming has in- creased the fragmentation in the policy decision process (Bonnen 1977). Hence the number of important actors who use farm income data in policy making has also increased since the time the data system was first de- signed. Within the Federal government there are two main branches which are concerned with policies affecting farm income. The executive branch has remained a principal locus of decision making in agricultural poli- cy. However, through time the primary nodes of decision activity have moved to higher levels in the executive branch hierarchy when compared to the 1920-1940 period when a high proportion of the decision making in the executive branch was focused at the bureau chief level. Decision making at this earlier time was characterized by what Randall Ripley and Grace Franklin call the "subgovernment phenomena" where interest 126 groups, Congressional committees and agency head or bureau chief level members of the exesutive branch dominate the decision process. When subgovernments are strong there is generally good agreement as to the appropriate direction of policy in a given area. In agriculture the fragmentation of interests brought on by increased specialization has led to greater conflict in agricultural policy and thus has moved the decision making up to higher levels in the process. This has weakened the subgovernment in agriculture so that important decisions on agri- _ cultural policy in the executive branch are now being made at the Assistant Secretary and Secretary level in USDA, in the Executive Office of the President particularly at the Office of Management and Budget and the Council of Economic Advisors, and even in the White House itself (Bonnen 1977; Cochrane and Ryan; Stucker, Penn and Knutson). In recent years, many other actors in the executive branch, such as the Secretar- ies of State, Commerce, and Treasury, the Special Trade Representative, the Special Assistant for National Security, etc., have also played an important part in the policy process (Bonnen 1977; Stucker, Penn, and Knutson). A priori, it was felt that these other executive branch ac- tors would be less concerned with farm income and more concerned with issues of direct interest to their specific positions than the actors mentioned earlier. The interviews with individuals in these tradition- ally nonagricultural_agencies and others seemed to confirm this hy- Pothesis. Farm income was not as crucial to the types of decisions with which these individuals normally dealt. In the legislative branch the important actors concerned with farm income fall into three basic areas: the Senators, Congressmen and their staffs on 1) the agricultural committees, 2) the House and Senate 127 Budget Committees, and 3) two of the research arms of Congress, the Con- gressional Research Service in the Library of Congress and the Congres- sional Budget Office. The appropriations subcommittees concerned with agriculture in both the House and Senate were at first thought to have a major interest in farm income data. However, since most of their ap- propriations work concerns the operating budget of the U.S. Department of Agriculture and only indirectly the income support programs, the in- terviews revealed these subcommittees to be less concerned with farm income data relative to these other Congressional users. Again there are other committees such as the Interior Committees which affect vari- ous aspects of food and fiber policy but their concern with farm income issues are not as critical as the groups mentioned earlier. Various private interest groups are also influential in the agricultural policy process. Thus, interviews with the general farm organizations such as the National Farmers Union, the American Farm Bu- reau Federation, the National Farmers Organization and the National Grange or commodity groups like the Milk Industries Foundation might also give insights into the private use of government data in public decision making. Also some other interest groups representing consu- mers and other interests were chosen for interviews to see how some of these groups outside of the "agricultural establishment" might use the farm income data. Thus, 35 interviews with the various actors in the public deci- sion process in agriculture were undertaken to obtain a more in-depth understanding of the use of farm income data in the process. Those in- terviewed were selected to represent a crossection of the roles and or- ganizations that currently participate directly in public policy 128 decisions for agriculture. Those selected for interviews included pre- sent and former members of the Department of Agriculture such as the Assistant Secretary responsible for commodity programs, the Director of Agricultural Economics, and various USDA staff and advisors dealing with price and income policy; agricultural policy experts in the Office of Management and Budget, on the staff of the Council of Economic Advi- sors, and on the White House staff; the relevant staff peOple of the Congressional committees and their research organizations; and the lob- .byists and economists of many pertinent interest groups. Interviews with 35 of these individuals were conducted during the fall of 1977 to determine the uses and needs of these policy makers with regard to farm incane. All interviews were made under conditions of confidentiality of individual respondent indentity. 4.3.6 RELEVENT INTERVIEW RESULTS The common expectation concerning the use of data in policy de- cision making would seem to indicate that data are important in the for- mulation of policy. Data should provide a source that along with analy- sis can produce information about problems that require government ac- tion. Insofar as farm income is a measure of the combined effects of changes in prices, sales, production and costs it should be a useful guide in policy formulation. Thus, farm income data might be used to monitor developments in the fann sector and to provide an impetus for policy action. However, none of the policy makers interviewed could cite any instances where the data on farm income alone led directly to any spe- cific policy action. Aggregate farm income data are used in the policy 129 process primarily to support positions taken by decision makers after these stands are taken. As one Congressional staff person put it, "knowledge fortifies bias.“ Most uses of aggregate farm income data seem to be in justifying positions that were already held and not in initial policy formulation, per se. Farm income data do not seem use- ful in placing issues on the policy agenda, rather, in most cases, the data are used merely as a tool in the debate. The nature of the political process itself may force farm in- come to a lesser role in policy formulation. Farm income tends to be used in reinforcing policy positions rather than in forming policy pre- scriptions because most policy formulation arises from constituent pressure or pressure from other decision makers in the process which occur before the income data are available to reflect the source of the pressure. One former Executive Branch decision maker noted that the timeliness of the farm income data, since they are for the most part, published on a yearly basis, causes many of the uses of these data to be ex poste, that is the data are used to justify positions rather than formulate policies. Another Congressional staff person felt that many politicians like to use the aggregate farm income figures because changes in the aggregate are much more dramatic in their impact. Since the main uses are primarily in speechmaking and the ex poste justification of policy proposals, the dramatic nature of changes in farm income are much easier to show when dealing with aggregate figures rather than averages. Another reason that farm income data are not used in the policy formulation stages of decision making on agricultural policy is due to the way the legislation is generally written. Agricultural policy has 130 tended to be commodity specific, aggregate farm income data are not, so in most cases farm income data must be used in conjunction with price data or cash receipts data by commodity to influence commodity policy decisions. If farm income data are not used to a great extent in the for- mulation of alternative policies the next logical place to examine their usefulness is in evaluating alternative policies after these are formulated. Farm income data do seem to have some influence in the de- cision process with regard to certain issues. In terms of Congression- al decision making a few interviewees felt that USDA farm income data are more likely to influence those Congressmen and women on the fringe of agricultural issues, i.e., those with nonagricultural constituencies or who are undecided on a particular issue. The major agricultural leaders in Congress tend to have their own informal information sources and thus rely less on published sources of data on farm income. This use by nonagriculturalists stresses the importance of understandability as an attribute of data on agriculture. It is doubtful whether any per- son unfamiliar with agricultural data would be able to make the distinc- tion between realized net farm income and total net farm income, so some confusion might arise because of this. The recent turnover in mem- bers of Congress and their staffs only exacerbates this problem. The apparent preference of Congress to use the notion of "cost of produc- tion“ as a basis for setting target prices as opposed to "parity" seems to be a reflection of the understandability of the data. Most urban members of Congress at least implicitly feel that they know the meaning of costs of production but for the concept of parity this understanding is not as prevalent, even though both of these in a sense are variations 131 of the same general concept. While no one suggested that farm income data were disregarded in decisions concerning various policy alternatives, many suggested that aggregate farm income as a statistic was given a rather low weight in the process. The analysis concerning the 1978 set-aside program for wheat provides an example. The Agricultural Stabilization and Conser- vation Service of USDA did a study that showed lower aggregate farm in- come under the various proposed set-aside programs. One high level Ex- ecutive Branch decision maker stated that this aspect of the analysis was given a very low weight in the process because a large error in the farm income data was assumed which would most likely overshadow the ef- fects of the set-aside on farm income, Second, the more important question of whose income is reduced was not answered, so the distribu- tional aspects of the effect of the set-aside might offset the aggre- gate effects. Another decision maker noted that aggregate farm income data were not very useful in evaluating different program alternatives, because the data are not sensitive to changes among policy alternatives. He felt that this arose primarily because of the way the data were cal- culated., The reliance on trends around census benchmarks and historical patterns in estimating the data tends to smooth out the income estimates and thus reduces the sensitivity of the data to specific dimensions of proposed policy changes. Other policy makers suggested that cash re- ceipts data are often more useful for comparing policy alternatives be- cause these tend to be more sensitive to the policy Options. These problems in using farm income data in program evaluation seem to have reduced the effectiveness of farm income data as a prime mover in decisions on agricultural policy. MoSt of the uses of the 132 data in policy were indirect or ad hoc, so other variables were often more important in the decisions. Variables such as budget costs and consumer prices and, in 1977, cost of production often become dominant in the policy deliberations. Another reason that farm income data have not been as critical as other types of data in agricultural policy de- cisions is the failure to debate the question of the need for government intervention in agriculture. Aggregate farm income is the primary sec- tor performance measure available for farming. Without serious ques- tioning of the need for special treatment for the farming sector, aggre- gate sector performance data which can be used to compare agriculture with other sectors are not as critical. Instead, the farm policy de- bates center on the distribution of the benefits and costs of the pro- grams. This creates quite different data needs which will be discussed in the next chapter. The principal focus of the debate on farm policy also effects the type of analysis needed. For instance, input-output models might be useful in program evaluation but as long as the farm policy debate does not explicitly consider the impact of farming on other sectors then the importance of this type of analysis is reduced. However, an observation is in order. A case can be made that an impor- tant consideration for agricultural policy is the increasing impact on agriculture of changes in other sectors. An obvious example in recent years was the concern among policy makers over the impact of changes in the energy sector or in environmental policy on farming. Thus, input- output studies and similar types of analyses might provide needed infor- mation for decisions in agricultural policy in some cases. Conversely, the greatly increased importance of agricultural exports in the balance 'of payments and the potential impact of farm policy changes and farm 133 sector performance on inflation reputedly now cause concerns among U.S. policy makers outside agriculture because of the farm sector's impact on various aspects of the U.S. economy. Nevertheless, no evidence of any of these policy concerns showed up in the interviews with policy makers primarily concerned with agricultural policy decisions. Prior to studying the system, a further policy use of farm in— come data that was considered was in program implementation. For exam- ple, many government programs or grants are made available to certain localities based on measured levels of unemployment as published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. There seem to be no specific examples of program benefits or other aspects of programs tied directly to USDA farm income data. Guebert noted that farm income data enter into the revenue sharing mechanism but this use is only indirect in that the farm income data enter into the overall income measures of a geographic area com- puted by the U.S. Department of Commerce. These are then used to allo- cate the revenue sharing dollars. This laCk of uses in implementation might also explain the seemingly low level of direct use of this farm income data in the policy process. It also suggests that changing the concept or definition of farm income might run into less political road- blocks. since few program benefits are directly affected by changing the concept or definition. However, the implicit ties of farm income to price parity might create difficulties since parity prices are pre- sently still used in implementing a few government programs. The sources and types of analysis found in the public decision process are also important in understanding the operation of the farm income information system. Until recently the primary government ana- lysts for public policy decisions in agriculture were in the U.S. 134 Department of Agriculture. The subgovernment phenomena and its domi- nance in earlier years of the decision process gave analysts at the lower levels of USDA influence in the process. However, the lack of conflict in the process also tended to reduce the need for analysis of alternatives. Recent changes, particularly in Congress, have shifted the relative importance of different analysts. Congress has increased its ability to do analysis in the agricultural policy area. The budget process in Congress has increased the demand for both analysis and more detailed data in Congressional decision making. The conflict between the Executive Branch and Congress that dominated the later Nixon Admin- istration years has also had a carryover effect which has caused Con- gress to rely less on USDA analysis of farm policy issues. Increased staff on Congressional committees, increased reliance on the major re- search arms of Congress, i.e., the Congressional Research Service of the Library of Congress, the Congressional Budget Office, and the General Accounting Office, and the increased use of paid private consultants have all reduced the relative importance of USDA analysis in farm policy decisions. Analysis is also provided by the various interest groups in i the agricultural policy process. While recognizing some of the problems mentioned in Chapter 2 concerning the use of privately supplied informa— tion in public decision making, the continuity of the decision process through time reduces the incentive of private interest groups to distort selectively the information that they provide. The use of private in- terest group analysis seems to be most important in Congressional deci- sion making and among those decision makers in the Executive Office of the President. Private interest groups are also more likely to be used for analysis on commodity specific issues since many of these groups 135 have a commodity focus and considerable access to information on their subsector of agriculture. Private consultants, especially those offering large econome- tric simulation models of the agricultural sector such as Data Resources Inc. and Chase Econometric Associates Inc. have become more important in decisions on agricultural policy. The Congressional Budget Committees and the agricultural committees all subscribe to and use these services as do most of the Executive Branch decision makers outside of USDA. One reason given for the rise of these private analysts relative to USDA ana- lysts are that the private consultants are willing to take more risks and project farm income estimates much further into the future than USDA. When dealing with a four- or five-year farm bill this can be significant, although it must be added that the USDA does produce unofficial fore- casts for these types of uses. This willingness to take additional risks is perhaps more important among the private sector users of fore- casts where USDA forecasts of sufficient length into the future might not be available. University researchers also provide a source of policy analysis in the public decision process. The type of analysis provided by these researchers is usually more of a long run, in-depth nature rather than evaluations of selected policy alternatives under deliberation at a given time in the decision process. As one staff person noted, it is difficult to get university researchers to reSpond fast enough to be of use in the policy process. It is apparent that timeliness in analysis is often as important as timeliness in the provision of the data. Lags in either of these steps hinders the use of information in the decision process. University researchers also influence government analysis 136 through professional ties with government analysts. Nearly all of the government decision makers reported using, to some extent, university sponsored research but the usefulness of it varied depending on the types of decisions to be made. The remarks of a Congressional staff person as to the relationship between research and policy making are somewhat enlightening in this regard. It seems that researchers tend to have quite different aims than policy makers. For the most part re- searchers want a product that is entirely defensible in the sense that it is comprehensive and correct, while policy makers must define a pro- duct that will be acceptable to their constituents. The policy maker does not necessarily care if he or she is right for the right reasons, so a policy prescription does not have to be entirely defensible. Thus, the data requirements for research and policy making are somewhat dif- ferent. When a researcher encounters insufficient data on a given as- pect of a problem, he or she is able to shift the focus of the research and thus can shift the risk to others by not dealing with this aspect of the problem. A policy decision maker is not often able to shift the risks brought on by insufficient data and must deal with the issue at hand with or without the relevant data. So insufficient data or gaps in the data on a given issue create problems which are often more criti- cal to the decision maker than the researcher. The use of various components and formats of farm income data seem to be somewhat different among those interviewed and the mail ques- tionnaire respondents. The data on farm income and number of farms by value of sales class seemed to be much more important than suggested by the mail survey. A reason for this, which was cited by many of those interviewed, was that for most of the decisions relating to income 137 distribution this was the only data available, so it received a signifi- cant amount of use. Comparisons of cash receipts data among various cr0ps and between crops and livestock also appears to be very important, this finding concurs with the mail survey. It was also suggested that cash receipts were used primarily because net income data by commodity are not available. Most policy makers recognized the problems associ- ated with the data on average income per farm and hence these were not used often in the decision process. Decision makers in agricultural policy at the national level also seem to indicate a much lower use of the production expense data than those who responded to the mail survey. Some interviewees sug- gested that the data was too crude for any major types of analysis. This coupled with the relative insensitivity of these data to changes in the short run also reduced its usefulness. A further consideration of the mail survey results would tend to confirm this. Only 18.9 per- cent of the Federal government respondents to the mail questionnaire found production expense data very useful while 40.8 percent of the re- maining respondents found production expense data very useful. While it is not statistically correct to compare these prOportions taken from an ordinal scale ranking, these mail survey results at least suggest an explanation for the interview findings. Another and much more limited set of interviews were used to develop information on the use of farm income data among two of the ma- jor user categories in the private sector. Six personal and telephone interviews with representatives of farm input manufacturing and banking firms were used to gather more in-depth information on their uses of farm income data. Individuals were selected from the Farm Income 138 Statistics mailing lists and an attempt was made to choose firms repre- sentative of these two user categories in the judgment of the researcher. All individuals were assured confidentiality in responding to the ques- tions. The schedule of questions was similar to that used for the pub— lic policy user interviews but concentrated primarily on how data and analysis was used and on deficiencies in the existing data. In the farm input supply industry, farm income data are used to gain an understanding of changing economic conditions in agriculture which then can be related to the demand for farm inputs. Cash receipts also tend to be more important relative to other farm income data in any econometric analyses of demand done by these firms. In part this is because of the way farm income data are estimated. Cash receipts ele— ments seem to induce most of the year to year changes in farm income. These changes are what effect the forecasts and demand estimates of these firms, so cash receipts become key data. As agriculture has become more specialized, inputs have become more commodity specific. The fact that cash receipts data are availa- ble by commodity increases its usefulness for input suppliers. Even in the case of a general input such as a tractor, commodity specific data are important. In general, the size of tractors used on various types of farms is different. For instance, knowing that dairy farms and to- bacco farms use more small tractors makes cash receipts data for these commodities more useful in estimating demand for these types of equip- ment. Since data on income and number of farms by value of sales class can be used as a proxy for income distributed by farm size, this type of data is useful in estimating demand for inputs which are used on different sized farms. The experience of a farm equipment 139 manufacturer also explains the relative importance of cash receipts as compared to realized or total net farm income in estimating demand for farm equipment. This firm found that most farmers pay for purchases of farm equipment out of the gross farm receipts and in reality the farmer does not generally distinguish between current and capital expenses. A further finding by the firm was that farm operators tend not to pay for farm inputs with off-farm income. So data on off-farm income are not as important in estimating demand. Three main types of farm input firm decisions are affected by farm income estimates: 1) production scheduling and inventory manage- ment, 2) marketing, advertising and sales strategies, and 3) financial planning for the firm. Production scheduling is often influenced the most by changes in estimated demand brought on income changes. If the firm already has an idea of its actual market share and desired market share and its actual and desired inventory levels, in the short run, most changes in demand will first affect production scheduling. Over a slightly longer period, changes in income may lead to changes in market- ing strategies which can be planned to account for these income induced changes in demand. Finally and to a much smaller extent, farm income data might influence investment decisions with regard to expansion of plant and equipment for manufacturing farm inputs. In the banking industry the uses of farm income are at the same time both more and less direct than in the farm input supply industry. Indirectly these data are used as an indicator of the economic health of the farm sector and as such are useful in decisions regarding the allocation of funds of the bank between agridultural and other types of loans. In this same manner the ability of farmers to repay outstanding 140 loans plus some notion of the future credit needs of farmers can be an- ticipated by monitoring farm income estimates. However, since most banks do not have truly national markets, aggregate farm income data are only useful in giving general indications. At the national level institutions interested in farm credit policy, such as the Federal Re- serve Board and the Farm Credit Administration, make similar uses of the data. The aggregate national level data are also moreimportant for these agencies than any specific bank for obvious reasons. Thus, for estimating the debt financing capabilities of the agricultural sec- tor or future loan volumes, aggregate farm income data have more of a direct use for these national level users. Larger banks or the "money center" banks often make a more di- rect use of the farm income data. The contribution of farm income to total gross national product and farm inventories to business invento- ries are of concern to these banks. This arises because of the need to anticipate reactions in bond markets. The bond markets respond very directly to changes in key economic indicators. Movements in personal income tend to be one of the critical variables and farm income is a major component of the personal income data series. Using monthly cash receipts estimates, a projection of the contribution of farm income to the monthly personal income estimates of the U.S. Department of Commerce can be made. Using these along with other data, an estimate of personal income can be made which allows the bank to anticipate the reactions of other banks in the bond market and thus make better decisions about the purchase and sale of bonds. It is also interesting to note that very little difficulty is encountered in integrating the fann income data into the national income accounting format used in the personal income 141 accounts. Uses similar to those described in estimating the contribu- tion of farm income to personal income arise because changes in farm income and farm inventories can often mask changes in the non-farm com- ponent of GNP and in business inventories. These latter two data ser- ies are important indicators in analyzing the business cycle which con- sequently impact on many economic decisions. 4.4 THE FARM INCOME INFORMATION SYSTEM Figure 4-2 is a schematic representation of the major components of the aggregate fann income information system. The following sections will describe each of the subsystems which make up the overall system. While these will describe the important individuals and organizations involved in the system, it must be kept in mind that the importance of farm income data in decisions varies to a large extent. The high level of nonuse of the data among those receiving the data through the mail from USDA coupled with the low weight often applied to these data in public policy decisions should be considered in evaluating this system. 4.4.1 THE PRIMARY DATA SUBSYSTEM The primary data subsystem of the farm income information arises because estimates of farm income, per se, are not obtained by sampling. Instead these estimates of aggregate farm income are built up from pri- mary data consisting, for the most part, of price and quantity data for farm inputs and outputs. The Statistics Branch of the Economics, Statistics, and Cooper- atives Service (ESCS) in USDA is the principal source of primary data for estimating farm income. For estimating livestock receipts the 142 5.53 22253“...— ES... 52.. N... -.. $52.. 33.37.? No TSPGNN 132:2; 3N:— _ ..ufio a mumm— nzoé NNNLNNE .N-.3.=u...N< F i _ 3.8.532..- N.... .3353 ...N—3.60....- mN—NN N..N 9.29... N...- co..Ne..m. NcasoN NE... .233 3...: EC 22.23.; 9.5.5. Nay—N.NN: _ xuhmamam N335? — 55593 gar—325:8”. 93 9::580... .3 ..N 9.22.3.8 9.3.... .2328. €2.93 5...... $95 «:33 En“. 3:9... 322:3 «.33.... 3959.3 8m: m .m» — u..< u .535 No 323 _ 3...“. No.3 .0 03!. .3 cogs—.539 5322.2. 3.8 9... No 8.3... .23.: 09.2.”. .9352: .02 32.2.3 8.339... 5.3... 333?. ..NN”. 033... EN». «0.. .33. 93o... .63.. No: N..N N33 N322... .553 _ 38.25 c2332. v.3.- NGNLN 2.2.5”. .I. 3.5.532..- .cuuom 83.... .5: No 3?..5 £33.. :3.- _ N..N...»an- 9.3.3:: N..N 9.255 .833 3N3... 2.2.3.3.... mum... ..NN... .225 SN: . 2:33. N..N 3.5.6 .283 E N N moo—to 3N2... Neon-.33.. ...N—..N _ N .N ..NN . . 285352.. 33:55”. 32.5 .035 3.3—:33 N .NgoENoLNcou 5...: II. $3.92. $3.25 ...N; _ goo—«.5 3.3—«3.559 39.9.8 .0 ENE: 3.3—3...: 1 3.333... I .:3... 2.3... E: 3:... N32. 3:... .23 ...u ...N< 2853. 3.... =. mwo_.m mum“ - 333:; S.E.-h... acme-:33 33...”... ..N... 8N 3.3 233 .83.. 3:32. a .3: .3533 “go: .N..Nz - NNN £3333 :3 55:5. 143 Statistics Branch provides production, disposition, and income reports as well as monthly marketing percentages to be used in distributing cash receipts over the year. The Statistics Branch provides somewhat more limited data on slaughter and feeder cattle sales. In the area of crop receipts the data from the Statistics Branch are clearly preemi- nent. Monthly prices for major crops by states and season average prices for minor crops and minor states are provided. State estimates of monthly marketing percentages and quantity marketed are provided for major field cr0ps. 0n the expense side, data are provided by the Statistics Branch on monthly prices paid for production items, interest, taxes and wages. The annual Farm Production Expenditure Survey data are important, parti- cularly for minor items in the expense accounts. Data on fertilizer consumption and purchases of livestock from inshipment estimates are also provided. Inventory quantity estimates for both livestock and crops are also obtained primarily from the Statistics Branch. The Census of Agriculture provides important benchmark data for estimating production expenses. 0f the approximately 50 separate ex- pense accounts estimated, most are extrapolations of benchmarks provided by the Census Bureau. Major accounts such as purchased feed and seed, fertilizer, fuel and oil, custom work and cash wages all are based on Census data. Benchmark distributions of farms by value of sales class are obtained from the Census of Agriculture and then adjusted each year depending on changes in prices and quantities of sales. The data on value of home consumption and non-farm income are extrapolations from Census data also. The Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service (ASCS) 144 provides monthly data on direct government payments which enter, with- out major changes, into the published government payment series. Com- modity Credit Corporation (CCC) loans and redemptions are also reported by ASCS and these are added in or deducted from the cash receipts esti- mates for those crops with CCC loan programs. The Economics Branch of ESCS also provides some data on the ren- tal value of farm dwellings and the value of farm buildings. This lat- ter item is important for adjusting estimates of depreciation and re- pairs of capital items. 0n the expense side the Economics Branch also provides estimates of taxes and interest. The Market News Branch of the Agricultural Marketing Service (AMS) in USDA provides data that are used primarily in estimating live- stock cash receipts. Data on slaughter numbers, the number of head shipped to public stockyards, placement numbers and weights from seven major feeder states are developed from AMS data. Private trade associations such as the Farm Implement Equipment Institute, the Limestone Institute and the American Feed Manufacturers Association are sources of data on capital expenditures on farm machin- ery, limestone expenses, and feed purchased, among other items. Private data also provide check data for the estimates developed in the ESCS Farm Income Unit. The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) produces data on compensation to corporate officers and corporate profits which are used by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). This agency uses the IRS data to adjust USDA farm income estimates to get farm pr0prietors' income. Much of the data collected in the primary data subsystem are not designed explicitly or solely for the income estimates. Thus, the 145 concepts used in the design of these data can cause problems which re- verberate through the system. One of the less apparent reasons that cash receipts data are used more often than many other components might be that the price concept used to estimate the cash receipts is expli- citly designed to yield aggregate income estimates. The concept used in ESCS: Statistics estimates of prices received by farmers is "That of a price which, if multiplied by the total quantity of the commodity sold, would give the total amount received by all farmers for that commodity" (USDA 1975). Many of the difficulties in the timing of the release of primary data used in farm income estimates alluded to in earlier studies (Hil- dreth, gt, 31,, Weeks, £3, 31,) can be viewed as measurement problems in the primary data subsystem. Since estimates of farm income are built up from primary data on prices and quantities rather than direct mea- surement of income, difficulties in measuring the primary data cause problems in the current system analogous to those which would arise in attempting to operationalize a concept of farm income under a system where income is measured directly. Thus, problems associated with the concepts, operationalization of concepts and the measurement of primary data then will tend to reduce the accuracy of the farm income data in the same manner as problems in the operationalization of a concept of farm income that is measured more directly. 4.4.2 THE FORMATTING AND COMMUNICATIONS SUBSYSTEM The formatting of this primary data into a form that has meaning and can be used as an input into the analysis subsystem is done primar- ily through the Farm Income Unit in ESCS. The various accounting rules 146 and relationships among the primary data are somewhat analogous to sta- tistical sampling procedures in other data systems. In this latter case statistical procedures provide rules for gathering individual cases into a single summary statistic. Accounting rules and relation- ships also provide a way for summarizing the primary data into a single or limited number of income measures. The Bureau of Economic Analysis uses the farm income data sup- plied by USDA but has a slightly different set of accounting rules and uses some additional primary data to arrive at a slightly different measure of farm income. Even though the underlying concepts of farm income used by USDA and BEA are different, the resulting income esti- mates are not essentially different. The reason for the similarity in measures arises in the Operationalization of these different income con- cepts. Since both agencies basically rely on the same primary data, differences in concepts cannot be easily operationalized. For instance, BEA attempts to measure a value added concept. Under this concept data are needed on total value of production to get fann output. Since these data do not exist the value of sales or receipts is substituted for value of production. This in turn forces the measurement of income or actually the formatting to be similar for the different concepts of farm income. Through government publications, particularly in the USDA's Farm Income StatiStics and Agricultural Outlodk, the data on farm income are then transmitted to analysts or directly to decision makers who can use the data. Some nongovernment groups also provide a communication role in the system. The news media, primarily newspapers and trade pub- lications receive the data and pass them along to other potential users. 147 Educational institutions also have a communication function. Teaching and extension education programs often are used to pass the data along to others as well as to provide some additional analysis on the farm in- come data. The BEA publication Survey of Current Business presents their estimates of farm output and gross farm product. However these data are not used to any great extent by agriculturally oriented decision makers. Most of these individuals seem to rely on USDA data. 4.4.3 THE ANALYSIS SUBSYSTEM The analysis function in the farm income information system is performed by many different firms and organizations. The Economics Branch of ESCS remains a major analyst of data on farm income which are used primarily in the public policy process. Indications are that the USDA analysis with regard to farm income for policy decisions is not as prominent as it might have been earlier. The increased ability of Con- gress to do policy analysis has perhaps reduced the role of USDA analy- sis somewhat. Professionalization and increases in the size of Con- gressional staffs have led to a greater capacity within Congress to do analysis on farm income issues. The Congressional budget process has also put new demands on data and the addition of the Congressional Bud- get Office has provided another source of analysis. Private consultants and interest group analysts also provide important sources of data interpretation concerning farm income. While the provision of information has traditionally been a function of inter- est group lobbyists in the decision process, the use of private consul— tants seems to be a more recent phenomena. Firms with econometric and 148 simulation models of the agricultural sector and the entire economy seem to be able to provide information on farm income that is both timely and pertinent to agricultural policy decisions. In the policy process these consulting firms as well as the interest group analyses are used the most in Congressional decision making and by those in the Executive Of- fice of the President as opposed to USDA. Educational institutions also provide analysis that is used in the public decision process but their analysis is in some ways different from other analysts. Academic research often suffers from a timeliness problem. It is difficult to use university analysis to a great extent in actual policy deliberations because policy makers are not often aware of ongoing research or when they are aware of this it is difficult to get a rapid response which is often critical. On line computer records of research currently underway in land grant universities as provided by the Current Research Information System (CRIS) might possibly help cape with this problem. University research is perhaps most useful in suggesting broader alternatives or on more longer run analysis of future problems and programs or in analyzing the impacts of existing programs. The maintenance of professional ties among government and academic ana- lysts is critical in the communication of the results of analysis and helps to foster the use of academic research in policy decisions. In private sector decisions, analysis by private consultants and more internal or in-house analyses are prevalent, although most finns seem to rely in part on USDA analysis. Banking firms might rely on some aggregate analysis done by the Federal Reserve Board or Farm Credit Ad- ministration but insofar as certain kinds of information have returns to uses that are almost fully appropriable by the firm, these firms are I49 willing to do their own analysis in these areas. In most of the pri- vate sector uses of data it is more difficult to separate the analysis and decision making functions because they are both undertaken within the firm. Thus, separate organizations do not exist for identification. The goals of firms in the private sector tend to be more easily identified than goals in many public policy areas so the analytical methods for dealing with farm income issues are probably more precise in private uses than in public uses of farm income data. For example, the uses of cash receipts or income data in econometric modeling seemed to be much more prevalent in those firms estimating the demand fer a product than in the public policy uses of the data. Thus, the types of analysis would appear to be more easily identified in the private sec- tor. 4.4.4 THE DECISION MAKING SUBSYSTEM The types of decisions on which farm income data impact can be classified into a rather small number of categories. Farm income data impact on public policy in agriculture but these are rarely key or cri- tical data because of the way policy is formulated. As long as the critical questions in agricultural policy do not center on the desira- bility of government intervention in agriculture then the crucial income data needs will be for more disaggregated measures, particularly distri- butional data, rather than for aggregate measures. The central actors in the public policy decision process in agriculture are in three main areas. First, in the Executive Branch, the Secretary of Agriculture and others in the Department are major actors and users of farm income data in this process. The important 150 economic advisors in the Executive Office of the President also have in- put into Presidential decision making. Agricultural economists in the Office of Management and Budget, on the staff of the Council of Economic Advisors, and on the White House staff itself are the most important farm income data users and policy decision makers in this part of the system. The second area of users and decision makers in the agricultural policy process are in Congress. In terms of their use of farm income data, four committees are most important. The agricultural comnittees in the House and Senate are users of the farm income data but more in the justification of given policy alternatives rather than as indicators for anticipating problems and formulating policies. The budget commit- tees in both houses of Congress are also important and their uses are somewhat similar to the agricultural committees. The apprOpriations subcommittees for agriculture do not appear to be major farm income data users. This arises because these committees only appropriate funds for the commodity price and income policies of the Commodity Credit Corpora- tion two years after the losses occur. These committees have no alter- natives in their ex poste decisions, thus their influence over current farm legislation is not as important as some other committees. Agricultural and other interest groups also influence farm poli- cy. The uses of farm income data by these groups varies somewhat, with the traditional agricultural interests concerned for the most part with commodity specific data. The way in which agricultural legislation is written leads to the concern for commodity oriented data. Even those interest groups outside of the traditional agricultural establishment are concerned more with the distribution of farm income and program 151 benefits than aggregate income. One might have thought that these groups would be questioning the appropriateness of government intervention in agriculture rather than expressing concern over which farmers benefit from the farm programs. Their attitudes might be explained by the na- ture of the public decision process, i.e., decisions tend to be incre- mental except in times of major crisis. At the state level the public policy uses were not as easily identified. Many of those receiving data merely act as a data source for others. However, one significant use of the data appears to be in estimating tax receipts for the state income and sales taxes. Some states also use econometric models in their forecasting of general tax fund receipts. Two major private sector end uses of the data were found. First, many farm input supply firms use cash receipts and farm income data to estimate the demand for farm inputs. In the short run these demand es- timates affect production scheduling within the firm and then such areas as marketing and advertising strategies. To a lesser extent decisions on plant expansion or other investment within the firm might be influ- enced by farm income. Among banking and financing firms, fann income data in a more general way affect the firms' estimates of the repayment ability of far- mers and thus affect decisibns on the allocation of funds between agri- cultural loans and other loans. Banks with a high percentage of farm loans might also use the data to obtain an indication of future loan volume. Trends in farm income also seem to be correlated to some extent with farm land values which also enter into financing decisions on farm mortgages. Investments by banks are also affected by farm income data. 152 First, the farm income projections give some idea as to the profitabil- ity of investments in farm input firms. Second, the effects of aggre- gate economic statistics on bond markets makes fanm income data impor- tant in that these are a component of these other aggregates. 4.5 SUMMARY The farm income information system has four major components. First, the primary data subsystem is composed of those public and pri- vate data gathering activities which provide the price and quantity data used to estimate the various farm income data series. Second, the formatting and communication subsystem uses a set of accounting rules and economic relationships to create income statistics from the primary data which then can be passed on to analysts and decision makers. Third, the analysis subsystem is comprised of the public and private organizations and firms which transform the farm income data into information for the ultimate users. Finally, the decision making subsystem includes the decision makers and decisions that rely on farm income information. Public policy uses dominate in this subsvstem but significant private decisions on the demand for farm inputs and the credit needs of farmers also are apparent. However, any discussion of the importance or value of farm income information should be tempered by the survey findings which indicate a high level of nonuse of the existing data by those who receive it. Possible explanations for this nonuse and its implications will be the subject offa major portion of the subsequent chapters. CHAPTER 5 EVALUATION OF THE SYSTEM AND IMPLICATIONS 5.1 INTRODUCTION Information systems, as part of social systems, tend to be characterized by problems which are ill-structured. The farm income information system is not an exception. A basic dilemma in dealing with any ill-structured problem is the imperfect knowledge which character— izes the problem itself. So solving the problems of the system are pre- cluded by the absence of knowledge about the exact nature of the pro- blems. Out of necessity, a major portion of the time and effort in evaluating the farm income data system will be spent in trying to de- fine the nature of problems in the system. In this way, the subject of this research differs from earlier studies in that by examining the nature of problems, rather than assum- ing a set of problems or purposes, it is possible to establish priori- ties for data improvements to meet the needs of decision makers. This chapter will concentrate on defining the nature of the problems in the farm income information system in order to obtain insights into the ap- propriate redesign of the system and will be divided into seven sec- tions. First, the question of priorities among users is addressed. This is followed by sections on the problems associated with conceptual obsolescence, credibility, national income accounting, and the feasibi- lity of changing the system. Finally, an assessment of the usefulness 153 154 of the methodology used in evaluating this system is presented. 5.2 DESIGN FOR WHOM The importance of farm income data in public policy uses as noted by the number of those surveyed who cited this as a primary use points to the role of government in supplying data on farm income. As was noted earlier, data collection and analysis for public policy uses is by definition an appropriate government activity. Since there are also some private sector uses of the farm income data, questions arise concerning the tradeoffs between designing the system to meet public versus private sector needs. In atomistic markets the social returns to improved data for private use often appear to justify assigning a high priority to pri- vate sector needs in designing an information system. Much of the pro- duction data and some of the price data supplied by USDA seem to have taken into account the private sector needs in designing these data systems. The fact that farmers are perceived to be the main benefici- aries and users of these data would also attest to the appropriateness of designing production and price data for private users since the mar- ket structure in agriculture would probably prevent farmers from or- ganizing to supply the data themselves. For farm income data, the survey results seem to pinpoint a different set of private sector users distinct from actual farmers or ranchers. Farm input suppliers are a principal private sector user of farm income data rather than the farmers themselves. This has impor- tant implications for the design of a farm income data system. The market structure among the major farm input supply industries is quite 155 different from the market structure of farming itself. 0f the 23 firms that were identified by the mail survey as farm input suppliers, almost 57 percent were manufacturers or suppliers of farm machinery and equipment. In a USDA report on the structure of the farm input industries, Strickler noted that seven firms were responsi- ble for almost two-thirds of all sales of farm machinery. The ferti- lizer and pesticide industries accounted for about 30 percent of the respondents. These industries seem to be best considered together since the majority of the farm input firms reporting use of farm income data in the pesticide industry were also in the fertilizer manufacturing in- dustry. This finding is consistent with the findings of Duane A. Paul, gt, al, (p. 13), who reported that 76 percent of the anhydrous ammonia producers or their parent firms produce chemicals and allied products in addition to fertilizer. The diversity in the fertilizer industry prevents one from estimating exact levels of concentration in this in- dustry. However, Paul, gt, 31,, did summarize their findings by sug- gesting that the fertilizer industry is relatively concentrated and this concentration is increasing due to horizontal and vertical inte- gration and certain barriers to entry. Both of the cited studies taken together would seem to indicate that overall, the farm input manufac- turing industries which use farm income data are relatively concen- trated. Given the theoretical relationships between market structure and government provision of information develOped in Chapter 2, the appropriate recommendation concerning the design of a farm income sys- tem would be to emphasize the needs of public policy decision makers relative to those private sector decision makers in the farm input 156 industries. Excluding the communication function performed by educa- tional institutions, their main use of farm income data was also in the area of public policy research. Thus, the needs of academic users of farm income data would seem to coincide generally with government and other public policy users. The other major private sector users of the farm income data were in the banking and financing industry. Of the 22 firms or organi- zations in this industry which reported using farm income data, 41 per- cent were institutions under the direction of the Farm Credit Adminis- tration. Thus, insofar as government credit policies toward agricul- ture are carried out through this agency the usefulness of the data in banking and financing industries is related to the usability of the data in public policy making in general. Based on the mail survey, local banks make up less than 30 percent of the users of farm income data in this industry, while large money center banks and investment firms account for nearly 25 percent of this category. All in all it would seem that the highest priority for the re- design of the farm income information system should be given to meet- ing the needs of public policy users of this data with private sector users receiving somewhat lower priority. This is not as important a distinction as it appears since many of the data needs of public po- licy makers were echoed by the private sector users of the data. These areas of overlap will be brought out, where appropriate in the follow- ing sections of this chapter. In order to approximate an intensity of use of farm income data, a question was asked on the mail questionnaire to assess the re- 157 spondent's willingness to pay for USDA provided farm income data.l/ The results from this question can only be used to make comparisons between the private sector users of the data since a substantial por- tion of the government users were unable to place a value on the farm income data or felt that because of their association with the govern- ment that it was inappropriate for them to pay for the data. Table 5-1 summarizes the results of this question categorized by user group. Based on willingness to pay for farm income data, the farm in- Put supply users seem to be more intense users of the data than the banking and financing users. The proportion of banking and financing users that are willing to pay nothing for the data is significantly greater at the 10 percent level than the prOportion of farm input sup- pliers who would pay nothing. At the same time the proportion of the farm input suppliers willing to pay more than $75 per year for the data was significantly greater at the 5 percent level than that prOportion willing to pay the same in the banking and financing user group. A possible conclusion from this is that among private sector users farm input suppliers should be given a higher priority since their demand for the data as measured by willingness to pay might be greater. These results do not hold when a comparison of the primary uses of data are made with the willingness of the user to pay for the data. Table 5-2 shows these results of this crosstabulation. The same limi- tations mentioned earlier also hold in this case. However, when com- paring the willingness to pay between those who use the data to estimate 1/ See Question 3 Appendix A. 1553 cm _ c _ o p N m N. gazm=< oz 3 a m N m m c m : 33 Ammewomcmm “caucus sea—cu o.oo_ o.cop c.co— o.oo— o.oo_ o.°o_ o.oop o.coF c.oc_ Hemogma so: o.oo— ..cw m.e ..e v.m a... N... o.e_ m.m~ .euop mecwaaacm as. wm m _— m. pm —~ mw we csapou ou:_omn« accuse; ce=_ou ..mw ~.cp o.cm ¢.om ~.m~ c.ap c.a_ o.om m.m sumo go “cause; 3cm o.oo— m.m_ m.m m.m o.m 0.x o.m m.mm m.m m=~o> a mum—a 35:3: .3 m e e a w e 3 e 3 use... muapoma< unease; ce:_ou m.m m.m o.m~ ..m o m.m m.mn o.e e.~ acoogom so: o.cc— e.g. m.—_ a.m o m... ~.pq ¢.m a.m mm» zucmacogm s- m w _ o N n p _ cash smuomcw mu=_omn< acougua :e:_ou «.mm n.mm o.m~ m.- «.mn ..mm m.mm o.c— «.me “caucus 30¢ c.cop m.o~ v.m ..m m.« o.mp m._— m.c m.om mka xocozaocu an N. N m m m s e m— cash mmoa ous—omo< .1 acoucam ca:_ou «.mm ~._o a m.- o.ce «.mm m.e_ o.o~ ~.mo acougoa 35¢ o.co— m.m~ o m.m m.o— _.~_ ~.m o.m “.mm cemN 35:3: an m. o m c A m m. 2 ous—omn< . so; cu page» maoocup acoEecm>ou u_uwz u:ou.:m=ou mc_u:e:.u apaaam u:u§:cm>oc copuau.um=~ mmwcm:——..: 2e: -.oum.x pauea mxmz muu>.cm agfixzem usa:_ pocoumu .ocepuauaum so macaw Esau com: mum: >m ucwucma 3oz c.oo_ N.c N.N N.o ¢.¢N N.NN —.__ m.m_ a mun—a accesses» me n — m pp mp m N cu m—acca waspomn< accuse; :E:_ou N.o c o N.N_ N.¢N N.N. o m.m “gouge; 36: o.cc. o c m._— ..Nc v.aN o N.—_ mN» senescent N. o o N m m o N cogu gwueogm manpoma< acaucmm cszpou N.NN m.N¢ c.om m.em N.¢N N.NN c.cm m.mN accuse; soc c.oo— N.o_ m.m N.o_ c.m— o.m_ v.mN o.m_ mN» aucoscmgm am e m o a _~ m— N can» mmmd manpOmn< “cause; gas—cu m.cm N.mm o.ov N.N— N.N— e.¢N m.mn o.om acougma 3oz c.oo— m.m o.N N.m ..pp m.N— m.N— e._m oEoN aucoacmcm on m e N m o— o— N— ous—cma< xeg ca ~ou¢h manage. co.uu:pa> uNuogu was :ONuaewumm xuwpom mgmnuo ca :orua5comc~ mmocmc——__: 30¢ -.mum_z use; o:.ucoc.u tease: u—paam go «we; pucucww mm: >¢m <¢ oh mmmz¢z_44~z N-m Ngmo_ one m. ans: .m— cwm.N Nmuovcoa we.“ mso+>wca EocN ummeazu usage. Eco» mo _m>m_ as» we: gqu 30: .N. vao.N NLOuumm o:_ageu as» No macaueoe e.se=ouo cones use age “as: ..N nem.N Nmeuuum co\u=o mco.mmc cooxuoa moucmemeu_u capes. age» as» use «an: .op ...NNN 3335.8 .5 5.3% No 3.3 3 39:232.. 2.3.: m5 9.... gen: .o pmN.N Nocaupau.cae ca away—ssou mmuczommc ecu cu message any use can: .m SNN 232: 22:2 2: co 52:83.... «5 3 2.5 .N mmm.N Ncouuum m=.scou we“ ewes—3 m.n=u_>.u=_ meose peace. we :o_u:a.gum.u on» m. “as: .c Noo.N Nmu——.Eau see» no o=_on ppm: oesocouo «cu m. «as: .m amc.N Nassau hemuocoe c. gouuom meweLeN «ea mo oNNm mg» m. «as: .e EN Nan—Nam Ea ca 2.85 ...5 a. :23 .m mmm.N Naommmepmaa see» ya quu:. as» m. use: .N mem.N Nmm_cum=e:_ cosao saw: oeuqecu menu—:u_cmu e? magnum; mgu on so: .— uccum gee: Emumxm zm vommmcvu< on Oh meo.umo:a .Aumozo— m. m ecu a»*ce_ga ummcm—g m. — oguczv m cu — we o—aum a co zepoa team—p nee—“mono ecu No oucmucoqe_ may use: .mgmguo co>o meovammac :_naeou cu co>.a on Nuvco.ca ween aega og_=aog ma:_ucumcou mucaemoc .go>ezez .m:o_umw=a mo mmaxu u:ocou».u News coxmca cu uo=m_mou as :au soumxm u=_u:=ouue «sous. ago» muamocmmu —a:owuoc < auco.umm=c .m:uu< <~¢uh_¢u zmumuo ch Gaza—mm< mm—h—«O—gg z