THE POLmCAL ECONOMY OF COPPER Dissertation for the Degree OfPh. D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY WILUAM JOHN BARCLAY, Jr. 1975 ..<........‘..._m;~...........,w“‘ ill/ll 29 .v19282 9839 \ W1 l/Illllll/Il/Il/l l/l/Il/l/l/I ‘ at This is to certify that the thesis entitled The Political Economy of Copper presented by William Barclay has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Sociology degree in Major professor ”7 Date 5/8/75 0-7 639 x O l\\ ABSTRACT @7‘ THE POLITICAL ECONOMY or COPPER BY William John Barclay, Jr. The multinational corporation provides both the theo— retical and organizational focus of this study. The partic- ular case examined is the political economy of the United States copper industry and the place of Chile and Chilean copper within this political economy. It is the multina- tional corporation which is both the dominant form of metro- pole capital and the key linkage mechanism between metrOpole and hinterland in the capitalist world political eCODOInY- Thus, the structuring of the amount, forms, and usage, 0f both actual and potential economic surplus in the hinter- land and the dynamics of surplus value accumulation in the metropole reflect the interests and priorities of the multi- national. The use of the political economy of copper as a case study brings together three larger issues: (1) the theoret- ica1 implications of the differing meanings of the concepts 0f economic surplus and surplus value, the core concepts Of neo‘MarXian and Marxian theory. reSPeCtively; (2) the prob- lem of the nature of the relationship between multinational L I C ..‘ b. ‘- ._~ Del a 9 :- ‘3 ’ u ‘ ”on..-” '9. a". P‘ -,. no. 0 . a O a. aflo- \- '3"‘ "I A... o z a -u I "‘ ‘u Unn‘.. l ‘0. .5. _‘ “ . I... s.' a“, .- I . .' o. . :' William John Barclay, Jr. capital and the metropole state which has been forged during the last half century; and (3) the question of the dynamics of colonialism and neo-colonialism in the contemporary world. The three parts of this study are organized around these three issues as they are illuminated through the political economy of copper. The methodology most compatible with a study of politi- cal economy and with the particular problem investigated here is that of historical-documentary methods. This meth- odology requires the use of a multiplicity of primary and secondary source materials. The information gathered from these materials is sifted and organized through a conceptual framework to produce a reconstitution and interpretation of the political economy of copper during the last several decades . THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF COPPER BY William John Barclay, Jr. A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Sociology 1975 This essay is dedicated to those who have been murdered bY the Chilean counterrevolution. May their brothers and Sisters succeed in the struggle for socialism and democracy. ii I... n. h V ' o o . . " u. a ‘O. . . “-“ r'. ... 0 -. ." vn. u.’ u ." .- HI..‘ .- . o ...‘ .- .“h~_ . ..’ ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to gratefully acknowledge the support and help given to me in this project by the members of my commit- tee: Ruth Hamilton, Rick Hill, James McKee, and Mitch Stengel. I realize that such acknowledgments are often simply a matter of form. In this case, however, my relation- ship with each of these individuals has been that of both friend and intellectual companion. Thus to single out any one of them for particular help in any part of this project would be impossible and also a violation of such a relation— ship. I would like to mention, however, that Dr. James McKee has demonstrated that it is possible to work within the university for a lifetime without losing one's humanity. This has been a particularly important discovery for me. Finally, I would also like to thank Pat Ashton, Len Berkey, Teddi Gamso, and Rhonda Levine for the faith they have shown in me and the support they have given me. Our relationship has turned graduate school from an ordeal of socialization into a process of intellectual and personal growth. iii "" - o... .H ‘K -Ah'_ ' u '0! -~'- Q"b-q,_ . \ """O-r.._ ’ ..o,... -. "\ N..." ‘. " A..- \ ‘. I ~.‘.-.'A. '0 u' . fl " I.- ‘u . ~-._ I ‘I. ~- u... . I -. Jo . “.h v Q. - . I .. _ 9.. .“i- l . I . \ l '. Qu“ . an n I. U" _ V‘.‘ I h .;\ a. “- " I! . y f.“ s I. 5. c i. ‘I‘ 'H ~~- ..‘ § TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF FINDINGS . . . . . PART I: THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS CHAPTER 1: ECONOMIC SURPLUS AND SURPLUS VALUE Definitions, Levels of Consumption, and Theories of Productive Labor . . . . . . . Discussion and Critique . . . . . . . . . PART II: COPPER AND THE METROPOLE STATE CHAPTER 2: COPPER AND THE STRUCTURE OF THE METROPOLITAN POLITICAL ECONOMY . . The Theory of Uneven Development and the MONOPOIY and Competitive Sectors . . . . . copper as a MonOpoly Sector Industry . . . The Kapitalistate as Instrument and Structure . . CHAPTER 3: AN ATTEMPT To INTERNATIONALIZE THE NATIONAL RULES OF THE GAME: THE STATE As INSTRUMENT . . . . . . . . CHAPTER 4: THE STATE AS STRUCTURE: SOCIAL CAPITAL.............. State Social Investment in Physical Capital: Diversification and Stockpiling State Social Investment in Human Capital: Ratlonalization and Diversification . . . State Social Consumption . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER 5: THE STATE As STRUCTURE: SOCIAL EXPENSES . . g g g o o o 0 0 ‘ ' ° The Domestic Costs of Capital Accumulation he Management of External Relations . . - iv 35 38 53 77 77 85 101 117 128 128 146 162 164 164 180 PART II CWTNm.6: CHAPTER 7 : CMWTMIB: BIBLIOGRAPHY TABLE OF CONTENTS (Continued) Page I: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILEAN DEPENDENCY THE ROOTS OF CHILEAN DEPENDENCY . . . . . . 200 THE APPROPRIATION OF ACTUAL ECONOMIC SURPLUS 0 O O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O O 2 3 0 THE LOSS OF POTENTIAL ECONOMIC SURPLUS O O I O O O O I O O O O 0 O O O O O 2 61 O I O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 27 9 It 'I "' hr.) .. p Q' r. J. I Table 1: Table 2: Table 3: Table 4: Table 5: Table 6: Table 7: Table 8: Table 9: Table 10: Table 11: LIST OF TABLES Selected Data on Sales, Assets, Employees, and Invested Capital, Big COpper and Fortune 500: 1954-1969 Big Copper and the U.S. Economy 1954-1969 . The Secular Deterioration of Wages Labor and Product Demand, Copper and the U.S. Economy . . . . . . . Chilean Copper Production in the Nineteenth Century . . . . . . . . Chilean Nitrate Production, Selected Years and Share of Nitrate Taxation in Government Revenue . . . . . . . Selected Measures on the Role of Chilean Mining, COpper, and the GranMineria............ Some Measures of Chilean "Underdevelopment" . . . . . . . . . U.S. Direct Long Term Investment in Mining and Smelting in Chile . . Two Measures of Chilean Loss of Actual Economic Surplus Through U.S. Investment in Mining and Smelting Chilean Copper: 1948—1970 . . . . vi Page 90 93 95 98 204 207 235 237 241 244 271 Figure l : Figure 2: LIST OF FIGURES TheGranMineria............ Hypothetical Structure of a Copper Multinational . . . . . . . . . . vii Page 225 270 q: INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF FINDINGS The theoretical focus of my dissertation is the linkages between an advanced capitalist metrOpole and an underdevel- Oping capitalist hinterland. I see the multinational corpor- ation, the dominant organizational form of capital in the contemporary world, as the crucial linkage mechanism. The internationalization of capital through the framework of the multinational corporation structures the amount, forms, and usage of both actual and potential surplus in the hinterland and the dynamics of surplus value accumulation in the metro— pole. The particular case I am examining is the political economy Of the United States copper industry and the place of Chile and Chilean copper in this political economy. In terms of my own interests, this study flows from four larger concerns: First, a commitment to the analysis of the Changing nature of colonialism and neo-colonialism, both international and internal. Here the multinational corpor" ation is a key factor in shaping the neo—colonial system of C1333 and strata, defining the course and limits of dependent Capitalist deveIOpment. Second, a concern with the emergence of the mUItinational corporation as the core institution of monOpoly capitalism and the new relationship between capital and the metropole state forged during the last half century. 1 (V. ’v M w..,..- ”.ana-i .ov- OO- u-o.' .. ,..... . . n... .. -~. ._' 1._ . .. 0.. “"' I‘. "V- s ‘1 ~. .._ - 'C'. k' -.. n L. 5.. . P “ I. I’— o _' h“ a“ ‘3 ~.‘. . . _ . .‘ K.- . I‘A‘ b‘.‘ ‘Q .. . ‘ u o'.‘ . . ‘ ‘e ‘. u _ ~ A y o . s u 2 To comprehend the structure and functioning of the capital- ist world political economy requires an analysis not only of the priorities and interests of the multinational corpora- tion but also of the manner in which these priorities and interests interact with the functions of the state. Third, an effort to elaborate the differing meanings and implica- tions of the Marxian concept of surplus value and the neo- Marxian notion of economic surplus. These distinct, yet complementary, concepts are at the cores of their respective Paradigms. In a nutshell, surplus value provides insight into the imperative of accumulation and thus the relation— ship between capital and the metropole state. Economic sur- plus illuminates the contradiction between that which is and that which could be produced in hinterland political economies Penetrated by metropole based multinationals. (These con- ceptions are developed at length in Chapter One.) Finally, and most importantly, these intellectual com- mitments are rooted in my opposition to the vast social and economic inequalities which are such a marked feature of the calPitalist world political economy. In fact, as this study argues, inequality is inherent in the very functioning Of this system. I believe that these inequalities are pro- fWildly damaging to the free development of indiVidua1 and SOCietal Potential in both metropole and hinterland alike. Thus, my theoretical concerns for understanding the world flow from and acquire meaning because of my COMitment to Change that world. Without that commitment to change. my ~. theoretical labor would risk becoming mere scholastic exer- cise. In turn, my theoretical work both informs and inspires my commitment to change. I The previous paragraphs were written in retrospect, as a summary of this essay after it had been substantially com- pleted. I did not, of course, begin this project with such a coherent and well-ordered conception of where I was going and the questions I wanted to ask. Instead, like all such Projects, this one grew, each part evolving out of what I had done before. In the following pages I will attempt to outline the evolution of my thinking, moving from my initial interest in and support for the Chilean struggle to construct a socialist society to my eventual focus on the role of the multinational corporation in the international political eco- nomy 0f copper. After this summary of my personal develop- ment, the remainder of this chapter is divided into two Parts. First I present the organization of the essay as a whole, outlining the questions and problems with which each 0f the following chapters is concerned. Then I discuss the mEth°d°1°9Y and the sources of data which are involved in a Project of this nature. Given my Opposition to the inegalitarian structure of capital as a world system, it was only natural that my SYN“ Pathies and hopes were kindled by the election of Salvador Allende ‘30 the Chilean presidency in September 0“- 1970' Of a- r I ’ o u '1 so - .o .«-vO w -..« -.p¢ -n. — u w‘ I‘ . ' - u..- .,.~. a course, I was also skeptical. There is, after all, a long history of the failure of the electoral route to socialism in Western Europe and the distorted face of socialist society in Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union. And then there was always the overwhelming counterrevolutionary presence of the United States in the Western Hemisphere. Nonetheless, I hoped that Chile might representa new break at the weakest lhm.in the capitalist chain (see Hobsbawm, 1971 for a simi- kn suggestion). Most importantly, the creation of a so- cfialist society in Chile would have significance far beyond between history and the field of soci— ologY has bee“ a subject of considerable debate, however. The dominant POSition is perhaps best represented by the combined PIOQUCt of a leading sociologist and (recently de- ceased) hiStorian, S. M. Lipset and Richard Hofstadter. In their book Sociology and History: Methods, (1968) Hofstadter argues that sociology, through its emphasis on the skills of quantification and conceptual generalization, can contrib- ute to the scientific standing of history (see his essay in Lipset and Hofstadter, 1968:1-16). Lipset's View nicely complements this conception. He suggests that the task of sociology is to create general propositions and that the work of historians serves, in effect, as a master file. of cases'by which sociologists can test these propositions (see his essay in Lipset and Hofstadter, 1968:17-58). This ap- proach to historical-documentary research carries over the logic of sampling to the study of historical patterns and historical change. However, as Moore argues, this procedure has serious problems, for it risks "gains in logical rigor and ease of manipulation..at the expense of..historical con- tent" (Moore, 1963:80). In contrast, I believe that it is more fruitful to con- sider historical-documentary research as an attempt to "per- ceive the general in the atypical or even the unique, re- solving in this fashion the tension between universals and particulars" (Moore, 1963:88). Thus, while the concern with ,.. _ c 1....--v~~ . Q’ 4 u. ‘ ‘ . a _ . a. ‘. a- o‘ ' § .n... " 0' 'D‘ ‘ .ua. nu" d 4 ‘ a - .....,_~_ .. "'3'... . .""UC. ." ‘ , '° pa .‘. '. ‘ "n. '[I 26 the relationship between the general and the particular re- mains, this approach contrasts with that outlined above which omits "more and more of the characteristics of what we are studying until the residue is something approaching pure form without content" (Moore, 1963:89). Historical-documen- tary research, then, requires the use of concepts which re- \mal structures when applied to history (Dobb, 1963zvii- \dii; Mannheim, 1936:200-201). As my discussion in sections 1 and II of this chapter made clear, I have drawn my con- cepts from Marxian and neo-Marxian theory. This theoretical tradition of historical materialism, and thus the conceptual framework I have drawn from it, is one of structure and func- tion which posits a hierarchy of social phenomena and inter- nal tensions (contradictions) in any social structure I (Hobsbawm, 1973:273-274, 278—289). Understood in this manner, historical-documentary re- search in political economy requires the use of a multiplicity of primary and secondary sources which are sifted and organ- ized through a conceptual framework. The outcome is a re- construction of the history which the researcher seeks to illmminate, a reconstruction which is at the same time an interpretation of that history. Further, the reconstruction involved is necessarily incomplete; "everything that hap- pened" can never be the goal of any effort to understand the social world. Thus my approach to historical-documentary methods differs from experimental and survey research. In both of the latter cases, hypotheses are formulated, data is 27 collected. and then the analysis is undertaken. Research using historical-documentary methods begins with a problem and a set of questions and a conceptual framework by which to tease out the answers to these questions from the avail- afle materials. As a result, the gathering and the analysis of information overlap, a characteristic this method has in cmmmon with field or qualitative methods. Historical- the wealth and expansion of the ruling class in a partic- tflar mode of production and to the wealth and expansion of flat mode of production itself.2 Capitalism is, of course, such a mode of production. Thus, in a society in which capital is dominant . our notion of productive labour becomes narrowed. Capitalist production is not merely the produc- tion of commodities, it is essentially the produc- tion of surplus-value. The labourer produces, not for himself, but for the capitalist. It no longer suffices, therefore, that he should simply produce. 41 He must produce surplus-value. That labourer alone is productive who produces surplus-value for the capitalist, and thus works for the self- expansion of capital (Marx, l967:Vol. I, p. 509). Although later writers have sometimes confused the issue, maxis explicit in his refusal to restrict the category of productive labor to that labor engaged in the production of tumnble goods or salable commodities. This conception is achmlly closer to what Marx called "Adam Smith's Second Eqflanation: the View of Productive Labour as Labour which isiRealized in a Commodity," an approach which Marx criti- cized in Theories of Surplus Value (Marx, 1969:156-170; see also Gough, 1972:52 on this point). Marx drives home his formulation in both general terms and with specific illus- trations of labor outside the sphere of goods production inn:which also creates surplus value. Thus, the definitions ofgmoductive and unproductive labor are therefore not derived from the material char- acteristics of labour (neither from the nature of its product nor from the particular character of the labour as concrete labour), but from the definite social form, and social relations of pro- duction, within which the labour is realized (Marx, 1969:153). An actor, for example, or even a clown, according to this definition, is a productive labourer if he works in the service of a capitalist (an entre- preneur) to whom he returns more labour than he receives in the form of wages; while a jobbing tailor who comes to the capitalist's house and patches his trousers for him, producing a mere use value for him, is an unproductive labourer. The former's labour produces a surplus-value; in the latter's, revenue is consumed (Marx, 1969:153). If we may take an example from outside the sphere of production of material objects, a schoolmaster is a productive labourer, when, in addition to be- labouring the heads of his scholars, he works like 42 a horse to enrich the school proprietor. That the latter has laid out his capital in a teaching fac- tory, instead of in a sausage factory, does not alter the relation (Marx, l967:Vol. I, p. 509). Fm:Marx, this definition of productive labor as embodied intme distinction between the clown and the jobbing tailor also establishes absolutely what unproductive labour is. It is labour which is not exchanged with capital, but directl with revenue, that is, with wages or profits (including of course the various categories of those who share as co- partners in the capitalist's profit, such as in- terest and rent) (Marx, 1969:153). {Hus brief account does not, of course, exhaust Marx's theo— retical development of the concept of productive and unpro- chxmive labor as the basis of the expansion of capital tjuough the appropriation of surplus value. Nevertheless, ‘U)summarize, while the line between productive and unpro- chxmive labor may be difficult to draw in practice, it is mnweptually clear. In the second portion oftfifisschapter I dmmmstrate that it is this conceptual clarity which gives tmaconcept of surplus value its analytical strength as a tmfl.for grasping the dynamic of accumulation in the capi- tafist social order. Before concluding this discussion, two final points mmt be made explicit. First, unproductive labor should mm be confused with unnecessary labor since "labor may be Imcessary without being productive" (Marx, Grundrisse, (muted in Baran, 1957:33). That is to say that labor such am is involved in the sphere of circulation or in the mech- musms of social control, may be necessary for the function- fig and preservation of a given social formation even if it 43 ribute to the social surplus product. Second, 1y emphasizes designation of labour as productive labour lutely nothing to do with the determinate of that labour, its Special utility, or the ar use—value in which it manifests itself 969:389). "they produce dum—dum bullets, opium, or por- els, workers produce new value" (Mandel, 1968: therefore productive laborers. Socially bene- cially harmful goods are equally likely to be f capital's thirsr for surplus value. In my scussion it will become apparent that the re- y consideration of the nature of the goods he categorization of labor as productive or is a second major distinction between Marx's rplus value and the concept of economic surplus. ecapitulate. I have now analyzed surplus value ically specific form of the social surplus capitalist society, indicated that the consump- ductive groups, but not of productive laborers n the concept, and examined the historically ction Marx draws between productive and unpro- I now turn to a paraflel discussion of eco- an and Paul Swezay's Monopoly Capital is un- .. ~_‘- best known and most often cited source for e concept of economic surplus. Despite the the concept to that work, however, the only ‘ "I ‘..r ‘1...” 44 definition offered is "the briefest possible [one]...the (fiiference between what a society produces and the costs of guoducing it" (1966:9). The subsequent addition of the mmlifying phrase "socially necessary" (which is nowhere (fiscussed) to the notion of the costs of production only mus confusion. While there is not space to consider all of Um resulting difficulties in detail (see O'Connor, 1966 and fimnfield, 1973:Chapters 1 and 2 for an analysis of some of I} the problems involved), I will list the major ones: (1) “‘” This definition combines output categories with income flows, a problem which is apparent in the statistical appendix that _‘ ‘ develops empirical estimates of the economic surplus. In ; arriving at these estimates categories of output such as total government expenditures are added to income categories smfllas total property income: profits, rent, and interest (Stanfield, 1973:86 makes a similar point in a different unmext); (2) The inclusion of the entire budget of the mate sector in the category of economic surplus is an "un- umml assumption for Marxists to make...If the main seats of Mate power are occupied by the corporate oligarchy, then state spending must serve ruling class interests. Thus, in the absence of government financial programmes, the corpor- ations themselves would be compelled to maintain utilities, transportation facilities, the health of the work force, and so on" (O'Connor, 1966:46): (3) Under monopoly capitalism the total product and mode of surplus utilization are not independent of each other, e.g., some of the new cars pro- duced each year would probably not be made if surplus were 45 1 through the sales effort; and (4) the same is :al surplus and mode of surplus utilization, iry spending which creates jobs vs. foreign in- Lch returns as pure surplus. ttely Baran and Sweezy offer a path out of the liCh plagues the Monopoly Capital formulation of rplus. In a footnote, they refer to Baran's 1 The Political Economy_of Growth (1957) "[f]or “a 5 ’f the concept" (1966:8), implying that their . “" 1nd use of the concept does not significantly ' that earlier work. The very brief discussion éi I! Capital (1966:9-10) which emphasizes the size :ion of the surplus as an index of the produc- lumaneness of a society also seems fully consis- Lran. Following this suggestion, I believe that rplus as used in Monopoly Capital can be under- : difference between actual output and essential Actual output is, of course, an easily under- lantity. Essential consumption is analyzed in .on of potential economic surplus below which fan's earlier works. Lran first distinguishes actual economic surplus 1 identical definition of the concept in both and in his later book The Political Economy of '). "Actual economic surplus [is] the difference .ety's actual current output and its actual cur- :tion" (1957:21). There is no great conceptual 46 ere and in fact the actual economic surplus is to measure even with the statistics collected t states. Baran himself goes on to equate it saving and in a footnote (1957:22) says that hat part of surplus value that is being accumu- s it excludes the surplus value that goes into ion of capitalist and other unproductive classes t portion appropriated by the state. In the or- formulation, actual economic surplus is equal to of I which is net investment. of its simplicity and closeness to more ortho- ions this version of economic surplus has not e most attention nor been the most controversial. a concept restricted to the effort to build a digm for social analysis (see for example :~Turner, 1941; Wolf, 1969). The strength of of actual economic surplus is its focus on the a society makes use of the resources available stment. This same focus also limits the con- r, since it ignores the difference between what available for economic and social development Id be available in any given society. Thus, it ncept within the parameters of the existing . Use of this concept as the only tool of anal- alling into what Harvey calls "hopeless rela- 3:219), an abrogation of the critical intelli- is supposed to inform social analysis. ‘1‘ J L P». v_- 1 1 an sil- 47 notion of potential economic surplus is an Jercome these limitations. He begins his :ussion of this concept by defining it as Eerence between the output that could be i in a given natural and technological ment with the help of actually employed Lve resources and what might be called 11 consumption (1969:273). is definition slightly in The Political Economy 1bstituting "employable productive resources" :3 I employed productive resources." The result of in wording is to add "the output foregone owing ence of unemployment caused primarily by the apitalist production and the deficiency of effec- (l957:24) to the three headings under which po- >mic surplus was seen to exist in his earlier short he has now added output lost due to employment to the category potential economic IS, potential economic surplus is the sum of aption, output lost through the existence of un- >rkers, output lost because of the irrationality less of the prevailing economic organization, >st due to Keynesian unemployment (Baran, 1957: ;h Keynesian economic theory was a product of E metrOpole capitalism and its economics, what : idle industrial capacity, lack of effective irrationality of agrarian structures in the de- :alisms of the third world suggests that this Lle modification of the concept for a grasp of 3 of the hinterlands of World capitalism as well. ‘W 48 ' to grasp the similarities and differences be- »ncept and surplus value, there are two ques- ’equire further discussion-~the idea of essen- .ion and the theory of productive and unproduc- .ich underlies the concept of potential economic ’ Baran the meaning of essential consumption is of real income necessary for what is considered 'elihood'" (Baran, 1969:277). This is similar F1 r .er political economist who uses a slightly dif- »t of potential economic surplus defines as rntial production: g i (mum amount of production required to main- (growing) population at a standard of ,ecessary to its survival. It includes 'duction contributing directly to the es- - consumption of the population and produc- ;uired to replace whatever capital stock .atural resources are used up in the pro- :isskopf, 1972:366). empirical determination of essential consump- .ifficult (See Stanfield, 1973, for an effort BLS budgets), the idea is theoretically clear. L on to point out, some effort at such a deter- .ften made by the state in times of war and ;is (Baran, 1957:30). .her clarification we can compare essential .o the level of consumption in Marx's model of Luction. The historically determined consump- productive labor force, the amount set aside the means of production exhausted during the 'ocess and the surplus value needed to support 49 twacapitalist and other unproductive classes at the same ]ewfl.of "decent livelihood" as the producing classes are allincluded in the concept of essential consumption. The mnqflus value which goes into the consumption of the capi- talim:and all other classes4 above the level of a decent livelihood is part of the potential economic surplus, how- ever. The theory of productive and unproductive labor that .1 t. Baran uses in his diScussion of potential economic surplus I l JR" :- is less clear. He defines unproductive labor as: all labor resulting in the output of goods and ‘" services the demand for which is attributable to the specific conditions and relationships of the capitalist system, and which would be absent in a rationally ordered society. Thus a good many... unproductive workers are engaged in manufacturing- armaments, luxury articles of all kinds, objects Of conspicuous display and marks of social dis- tinction. Others are government officials, mem- :bers of the military establishment, clergymen, (lawyersv.advertising agents, brokers, merchants... (Baran, 1957:30-31). were (are two significant differences between the productive/ 1;; unproductive conceptualization of the 1952 article and this defiJtition taken from The Political Economy of Growth, pub- hshedi in 1957. (1) In his earlier article Baran mentions in passing workers "who are engaged in the PrOduCtion Of “Wkwesgéntial goods" (1969:277), but his discussion is cast solely in terms of those workers "not directly related to the process of production" (Baran, 1969:277). Thus. exam- ples given are physicians, artists, advertising agents, galmjblers, etc. but none of the labor force in manufacturing. H oweV’er, as the above quotation demonstrates, certain groups .In 50 of manufacturing workers are explicitly included in Baran's 1957 discussion of unproductive laborers. (2) Second, there is his treatment of what might be called the "socially use- ful" professions--scientists, physicians, teachers. In his first discussion of the concept of potential economic sur- plus, Baran classifies the people in these professions as unproductive workers. When he revised the concept for The J Political Economy of Growth, he explicitly excludes these groups from the category of unproductive labor. He does so “'1‘ on the grounds that the demand for their labor "would become multiplied and intensified to an unprecedented degree" in a ' is" a» "rationally ordered society" (Baran, 1957:33) . Even though these services are socially useful and would be expanded, he nevertheless characterizes these groups as "supported by the economic surplus" (1957:34) . Thus, despite his step ’ away from Marx's formulation of productive and unproductive labor, Baran seems unable to abandon it entirely, and his own S(:hema remains somewhat ambivalent. Once again it is useful to compare this conceptualiza- tion with the productive/unproductive classification devel- Oped by Marx. The central difference is as follows: Marx's clas'Sification of productive and unproductive labor is firmly rooted in a historically specific theoretical anal- Ysis of a given mode of production. Productive labor con- tributes to the wealth and power of that society and thus to the Wealth and power of the ruling class. Baran, on the other hand, specifically rejects this approach to the issue: — 51 what is productive and what is unproductive labor in a capitalist society cannot be decided by ref- erence to the daily practice of capitalism...the decision has to be made concretely, from the standpoint of the requirements and potentialities of the historical process, in the light of objec- tive reason (Baran, 1957:32; see Baran, 1969:275 also). Thua,except to the extent that the level of "essential con- sumption" is historically variable, productive labor for Baran remains a historical category. Further, as a result of his focus on irrationality and waste, he approaches the n? theoretical question of productive and unproductive labor I through an analysis of unproductive labor in specific modes ; I"! Y 0f production with productive labor emerging as a residual E3 category. Marx develops an analysis of productive labor and SOCial growth so that unproductive labor is the residual Several other distinctions flow from this difference in ’u." ‘3“mCEEnualization. First, and most obviously, some workers thnl are productive in Marx's schema are unproductive for Bazul and vice versa. Examples of the former would be those engaged in the production of sophisticated alarm systems for Um Errotection of factories, in the manufacture of new- fmxfiled potato chips, and in the creation of luxury goods ku‘czapitalist consumption. The latter, those productive for Baran but not for Marx, could include family farmers, artiSts, and independent professionals. Since the work of both authors was part of a critique in praxis of capitalist Society, this distinction is of more than purely theoreti- Cal interest. Socialists have often argued that those — 4 52 emmged in productive labor have the greatest potential for ckms consciousness and thus should be the focus of social- istpmlitical activity. Thus, different conceptions of pro- munive labor have direct implications for socialist strat- egy. (On this point see Cherry, 1973:60—65 and Gough, 1972: 71-73). Secondly, Baran's statements to the contrary not- withstanding (cf Baran, 1957:33 and 1969:275), nobody in his model can be said to "live off the surplus" since essential consumption of all individuals is defined as outside the po- tential economic surplus. Of course, some groups--and to smme extent these are Baran's nonproductive groups--consume more of the surplus than others, that is to say that excess ccmSumption is differentially distributed. In Marx's model, or'the other hand, unproductive groups do live entirely off Um sOcial surplus product. Finally, for Marx, those who ‘*—uve<3ff the-social surplus product are not productive ” “erzrs. In Baran's analysis, however, some peOple who are “Tpoisted largely from the potential economic surplus may ago 13a productive workers, e.g., doctors or teachers. IXfter considering these differences of conceptualiza- ti“on: I have decided to use the discussion and definition ofactual and potential economic surplus in The Political BEEEflmy of Growth as the basis for my own analysis through- out'the remainder of this chapter and for the study of the political economy of Chilean dependency in Part III. There a O I O 0 re three reasons for this chOice. First, as the prev1ous d . 18cussion has indicated, these are by far the most powerful a. .1- H 53 ofthe different concepts of economic surplus that Baran amiSweezy have developed. Second, they are also the most mnweptually rigorous. Although Baran had already devel- opaihis own theory of productive and unproductive labor at the time of his 1952 article, he still remained at least partially under the spell of the analogous Marxian cate- gories. This accounts for some of the confusion in the earlier discussion. Finally, as already noted, this same I1 book is the referenCe cited by Baran and Sweezy themselves y at the end of their brief discussion of economic surplus in fiygmmly Capital, indicating at least some satisfaction with 1 tihat version of the concept of economic surplus. Discussion and Critique (Dn the few occasions that either Paul Baran or Paul ””-&mezy'havevdiscussed the relationship between economic sur- Mus 61nd surplus-value, they have always stressed the con- hnuii:y and similarity between the concepts. Baran's foot- rmteS» in The Political Economy of Growth (1957:22 and 23) suggest that the difference involved is a quantitative rather that a qualitative one. Thus he states that potential eco- nomic surplus excludes such elements of surplus value as... essential consumption of capitalists, what could be called essential outlays on government admin- istration and the like; on the other hand, it comprises what is not covered by the concept of surplus value--the output lost in view of under- employment or misemployment of productive re- sources (1957:23). — 54 In Monopoly Capital the two concepts are linked even more directly. The authors justify their choice of economic surplus as their major theoretical tool by arguing that "in a highly developed monopoly capitalist society, the surplus assumes many forms and disguises" other than the sum of profits, interest, and rent with which surplus value "is probably identified in the minds of most people familiar with Marxian economic theory" (Baran and Sweezy, 1966:10) . Recently, Sweezy has reiterated the argument of continuity between the two concepts. "At no time did Baran and I ex- plicitly or implicitly reject the [Marxian] theories of value and surplus value but sought only to analyze the modifica— tions which became necessary as the result of the concen- tration and centralization of capital..." (Sweezy, 1974:32) . Nor have Baran and Sweezy been alone in this belief in con- ».._Ceptua1 continuity. Several other writers, e.g., Nicolaus (1969309410) and Gough (1972:72) have accepted this claim of continuity in their own comments on the concept of eco— nomic surplus. However, as the discussion of the two concepts has al- ready demonstrated, they rest upon quite divergent theories of Productive and unproductive labor. This divergence flows from the radically different use of historically rooted Categories in the two concepts. Equally important, potential ecorlomic surplus, through its stress on the output lost due 1: . . . . . 0 the wastefulness of the ex1sting soc10economic order, in- cludes an institutional critique which is absent from the i m 55 concept of surplus value. It seems that, just as Baran's theory of productive and unproductive labor remained par- tially under the spell of the analogous Marxian categories, so the two authors did not fully realize the distinctive nature of their new concept. Rather than merely extending surplus value to the conditions of monopoly capitalism, Baran and Sweezy, along with subsequent analysts, have de- veloped a conceptual tool which has different uses and il— F. luminates different facets of the reality of advanced capi- talist societies. None of this is meant as a denial of Sweezy's insistence that he and Baran never rejected the 4: theory of surplus value but rather to point out that the L: same theoretical framework cannot be the basis of both sur- PluS Value and economic surplus. Instead, I am suggesting that the usefulness of the new concept exceeds that of sur- .-_plus Value on »some dimensions, but is more limited on others. Perhaps the best way to approach these issues is through the divergent uses of historical categories. The most Striking difference between the two concepts is the histor- ical generality of economic surplus and the historical spe- cificity of surplus value. In his earliest discussion of e“nomic surplus, Baran (1969:280-285, 291-294) applies the concept to modes of production as varied as the prehistoric Middle East, the Roman Empire, feudal Europe: and the con- ter“porary United States. Five years later, in The Political E . %y of Growth, economic surplus is used to analyze a w' _ . lde range of non-Western societies while Monopoly Capital — 56 :e, an affort to understand the U.S. political 1 economic surplus the major conceptual tool. ' hand, as I have already demonstrated, in Marx's .us value is the monetary form of the social sur- .. Thus it exists only in modes of production .ge value appears. This limits the concept lhe analysis of the capitalist mode of production 'plus value may also be found on the margins of .t societies, particularly where the monetariza- ' distance trade has occurred. The reason for .ion is that, like all of Marx's concepts, sur- ‘5 relational (Ollman, 1971), that is to say that L a particular social relation, a dialectic, be- :ers and non-producers. I national or dialectical nature of surplus value .most clearly by placing it in the context of 'sis Qf the labor process and the rise and de- lode of production. For Marx the social rela- a labor process were the fundamental element in z of any mode of production since they distin- specific mechanism by which surplus labor was .f the producing classes by the non-producers '3:226). Thus, it is only under the capitalist [notion that free wage-labor meets capital in the 'ther, Marx saw that this freedom of the laborer as: freedom to dispose of one's own labor time Lied by freedom from any claims on the means of .7; . L'Xlu C l . ~01 "I 57 mnmistence except that which could be purchased in return fin'the sale of one's own labor power. The latter freedom ensured that the former would be exercised, or, as Edmund make was the first to make explicit, the whip of hunger wmfld.force the laborer into the market to seek employment fnmlcapital (Polyani, 1944:116-117). It was on the basis ofthis sociological condition--which "comprises a world's Ifistory"--rather than the economic model of equal, autonomous amyms who meet in the market, that Marx constructed an en- thm critique of political economy (Horowitz, 1970:156-158). The employment of the laborer by the capitalist results inthe production of surplus value while the aggregate of imfiyidual surplus values describes the relationships be- Ummlthe capitalist class as a whole and the proletariat asiiwhole. It is in fact the labor of the individual pro- -_1eUHian that-creates the individual capitalist just as it ‘iistme labor of the collective proletariat that produces theeapitalist class. Thus the dialectic is both micro and macro: ...[C]apital presupposes wage-labor and wage-labor presupposes capital. They mutually condition one another; they mutually bring each other into exis- tence...[C]apita1 and wage-labor are the two sides of one and the same relation. The one conditions the other (Marx, 1948:38-39). &mdlar1y, the conditions necessary for the existence of the capitalist are those which call into being the proletariat. Surplus value thus strips away the veil of appearances woven by the interaction of commodities, of things, in the market and reveals the labor process, the social relations of pro- duction (see Marx, 1967:Vol. I, pp. 71-73). 58 The concept of economic surplus, in contrast, is built Imither upon the labor process nor upon any other social relation. It is defined in the aggregate, for society as ammole, and cannot be represented as the sum of the sur- gfluses created from the social relations of individual la- uners and capitalists. Clearly the output lost due to the hrationality and wastefulness of the prevailing social mfler is not appropriated since it is never produced, thus Here is no social relation involved. Thus, the dialectics ofgmoduction, exploitation, and class conflict, integral toany class based mode of production, are virtually ignored. hmMonopoly Capital, for example, the use of this concept lemms us with a contradiction of monopoly capitalism, the temmncy of the surplus to rise, that is a contradiction Wifimut an agent and therefore moves in a void. The lack - -Ofan internal contradiction which drives the system forward iSunderlined_by-the very language used when the economic Sumflus is discussed. Both authors repeatedly write of "Smfiety" doing this, or of economic surplus as an index Of"society's" ability to do that. In fact, when Baran inupduces his discussion of economic surplus, he does so hiterms of an analysis of "comparative statics" which "ig- rmre the paths of transition from one economic situation to another" (1957:22; see also 1969:273). Yet there is a dialectic involved in the concept of economic surplus, a dialectic that Baran himself explicates when he writes 59 tegory of potential economic surplus itself ends the horizon of the existing social relating as it does not merely to the easily able performance of the given socioeconomic zation, but also to the less readily visualized of a more rationally ordered society (1957: phasis added). rplus is thus a product of Baran's lifelong strug— ire reality by reason, "to point out the...dis- tween the objective capacity for the creation of ne social order and the socio-political struc- h maintains itself as a system of social imbalance nality: (O'Neill, 1969:XXVI). The dialectic which roots of the concept of economic surplus emerges arcusean one, the tension between the is and the sen that which exists and that which could be. , while surplus value goes behind the appearances at to a deeper level of social relations, econom— transcends these appearances, going to the plain son.5 , what Baran has done is not, as a recent and Jite useful article by Ian Gough suggests, to historical viewpoint which Marx utilized to rkers in the circulation process from production Jugh, 1972:67) to the categorization of all pro- unproductive labor. Instead, he has chosen a that is intellectually outside the prevailing c, that is unencumbered by its values...and... 3 critical insight into that social order's con- 6 and hidden potentialities" (Baran, 1969:275). 4-_4.—- .- 60 Mae we have a paradox. It is precisely this position out- fide of history which enables Baran to make historical cate— mmizations of productive and unproductive labor, illumi— rmting the irrationality of a given social order. This flmus on irrationality has given his work, and that of his aflleague Paul Sweezy, much of its moral and political force. mlthe other hand, it is this same position that turns &uan's conception of economic surplus into merely a cate— mny of political ecOnomy rather than also a social relation ofexploitation as in the case of Marx's own conception of suqflus value. At the conclusion of this chapter I will try tosuggest some of the larger socio—historical reasons for this difference . At this point the discussion has laid the basis for the (mnfideration of the strengths of each of the concepts as .r-flmmestrengths bear on the analysis in Parts II and III of "thnsessay. hefore proceeding, however, it may be worth- Whfle summarizing the argument to this point. First, al- thmmh Baran and Sweezy themselves insisted on the similar- itkm between economic surplus and surplus value, I argued thatan examination of the divergent theoretical bases of tMatwo concepts called into question this claim. I then Ingan to consider precisely how the two concepts differed, fbcusing on the historically specific nature of surplus value and the ahistorical nature of economic surplus. I next demonstrated that the historical specificity of surplus value was rooted in a social relation and dialectic peculiar 61 to the capitalist mode of production, the confrontation of capital and wage-labor in the market. Thus the concept is cum of change, an attempt to grasp the dynamic of an entire qmch. .Economic surplus, on the other hand, is located not huany social relation but in a dialectic of reason which adsts outside of, or beyond, history. This dialectic of ‘Uwught is the origin of both the strengths and limits of Um concept. Now we are ready to turn to an examination of muplus value as a way of understanding the central impera- thm of the capitalist mode of production, the accumulation ofcapital. Then I shall discuss economic surplus as a con- cqmual tool for the analysis of the relationship between pofitical economic units in a system of dominance and sub- onfination. The final pages of this chapter are devoted to a mmiology of knowledge consideration of the two concepts. "The fundamental problem to which Marx's sociology was “amnessed was the_systematic explanation of structural - Us.'_: R o 79 includes them since the social relations of production and the pace of technological change are similar to that pre- vailing in consumer durables. Bluestone's (1972a:65-66) summary of the concept ties the sociological and economic imperatives, the regional and sectoral processes together and is worth quoting at length: The simple dynamics of profit maximization, espe- cially in a period of monopoly capital, produce a tendency toward a 'secular deterioration of terms of trade' between nations, between industries, and between social classes. This occurs for two reasons. First, invest- ment in a dynamic economy tends not only to in- crease the capital intensity of the product or factor in question, but also changes the quality of the factor so as to make further investment technologically profitable. Capital investment in a given product, for instance, often increases the market value of the product, thereby strength- ening the profitability of renewed investment. Higher past profits can also be used for research and development, which further expand the market for these goods. Profits also allow expanded advertising, which reinforces this tendency. On the other hand, new capital, products, or people that originally fail to meet the test of the market, like many infant industries, seldom re- ceive additional investment and consequently are doomed to deterioration. The second reason for a dichotomization within society derives from the potential redis- tributive effect of any given investment. While it may be true that continued investment runs into diminishing marginal returns, capitalists will tend to link efficiency and distribution criteria in investment decisions. Private in- vestors will tend to reinvest their capital in areas which promise the highest relative return only if such investment does not tend to alter the long-run income distribution in such a way §§_to reduce their own relative standing. The capitalist has both a psychological and a po- litical stake in an unequal distribution of in- come, and consequently often measures his success not by the absolute amount of accumulation, but by the relative surplus he accumulates compared ....L r 0.04 ‘ ..I~1:‘ ...i II I a i ‘ "I.: ’O'GO‘I U M 614 J. .v u. a“. s O. Ott‘ , 7‘0»? 96".- a v... “cc“ 4. *o .- . . ‘ be '8 3.... An. "§v4| ‘ I. I o C ‘J'QA - u v V ‘ ..r . ."‘-‘ 80 with others..Seldom will the maximization of private returns constrained by this distribu- tional objective coincide with the maximization of total social returns. The outcome, of course, is uneven deve10pment where the rich become richer and the poor more impoverished. Thus Bluestone deve10ps Gurley's stress on the private rationality behind building on the best as the non-techno- logical determination of this sectoral dichotomization. That is to say that rather than the primary/secondary/ tertiary categories which conventional wisdom deduces from technology, (compare Bell, 1973:Chapter 2) the theory of un— ewen development makes clear that the sectoral divisions of the political economy are rooted in the social relation- mfips of production and accumulation. Of course, as I shall augue below, the dichotomous model of the U.S. political emonomy is incomplete. The state sector, whose very ration- ale is rooted in this tendency toward dichotomization, turns ”‘ Hithe‘model into a trichotomy. With this by way of introduc- O‘tion, let me now turn to a sketch of uneven development in thelJ.S. as it appears in the monopoly and competitive sec- tors outlined by O'Connor (what follows draws heavily on Franklin and Resnick, 1973:74-83; Fusfeld, 1968; and (PConnor, 1974:13-16). The monopoly sector is the locale of big capital and tug labor, of the multinational corporation, and is the po- litical economic base of "the more sophisticated leaders of America's largest corporations and financial institutions" (Weinstein, 1968:ix). These are the class conscious entre- Ineneurs whose vision of the entire political economy and .1' 4..- O 9w- : ‘OO: I n .1.- n n n I‘I‘ vc:' . *v-. I v‘ 0-- - u... ’0; v”. - I F : a I ‘0 . “‘~Y O . -.l l \‘ ‘ .1 I ‘ I . I ".: ‘n .._ u .l 'I a . q I .I ~‘ ' ‘9 3., \. b. .-\: t II . t ‘2‘ ‘F‘ i ' ‘v c . ,. t, i‘. C?- ‘ ‘l I .‘u . V I .. 81 ability to subordinate the market to corporate rationality has been the source of the political economy of modern U.S. liberalism: the welfare state at home and the open door empire abroad (Weinstein, 1968:4-5). This elite sits across the bargaining table of class collaboration from those labor leaders Mills called the new men of power. Behind the latter are the giant unions whose wage and benefit contracts set the standards that others seek to emulate and that the small businessman fears: the steelworkers, the Teamsters, tie United Auto Workers. These men, these unions, and their power are as much a part of the monOpoly sector as are their corporate partners. It is the fortunes of this sector that lie behind the fluctuations of the GNP growth rate, the American Challenge, and much of the rising--at least until 1965--rea1 income which is the basis of the "American stan- -~ _ dard of living." This is the-visible sector of the political economy-- Heel, autos, chemicals--and is what most of us, including mute a few economists and political leaders,have in mind vmen we speak of "the U.S. economy." The Fortune lists--the Hm leading industrials, the 50 largest commercial banks, the 50 insurance companies whose assets dwarf the others-- areidevoted to the celebration of this economy. All the Corporations which appear on the now numerous company/ country comparison tables are drawn from this sector. What can we say about the characteristics and trends of the 'Mbnopoly sector? In a nutshell: both invested capital and ..uvI‘ .’..pv . .4... -u' o 4". O 10"- ,_ saw I :4. Q g I .< ...u o .9 n O u.;' F u. v I”! h '-o. C — u . O I"~ -- ~— ..~' -."‘:I ‘.‘«. s P §.‘ ..- ‘ ‘ ‘\ I -.. .W a o ~ ‘.:.‘~ § .‘. a p .A \ k‘ I U \ iv. ”a ...- "-. "< i 'x .‘ n in, “u O Q . X 'x -I': u,‘ 82 productivity per employee (white or blue collar) are high and increase over time, wages and salaries are attractive, and profits are ample. The demand for the output of this sector increases relatively slowly and this fact, coupled with rising productivity means a rate of labor absorption that lags considerably behind the growth of the labor force. Some of these companies and certain industries may grow slower or faster than others but, except in times of major crisis (e.g., the Penn Central) they do not go out of busi- ness: the continuity of names and industrial distribution on the Fortune 500 is quite impressive. Here the world of the Smithian entrepreneur has been left far behind and bears a relation to reality somewhat analogous to the rationalization of U.S. agricultural policies in terms of the need to preserve the family farm. The New Deal/WWII .-response t0»the Great Crash cemented the corespective be- 'tmvior of the large corporation and the big union. Thus jobs are steady, working conditions are good, and retire- nent will bring a pension check sufficient for a decent Jife--if inflation is kept under control and no major medi- cal problems develop. But this is not all there is to the U.S. political economy. The contrast with the competitive sector is a Sharp one. The latter is the milieux of small capital-~the Rpm and pop grocery store, the local textile mill, the town bank--of a disprOportionate number of part time employees, and a good portion of the 65 percent of the nonagricultural no A: the .— U‘ be! . ‘ I u: "I"! ‘~- a... '1‘; " nu.‘ . In. .uu .': :F" “I. P in.“ O ‘I - ' ."FR- . " "mun..- 2::"3'fi : ..“Hbsl “‘ b to. ‘On I" I D 2 ,. J It" i '5‘. '1 ‘o ~.RA 'y' A” a V ‘ ‘.th‘ in“. N‘s. + ‘.'b h.)- U‘ .‘. cg ‘ ‘ av- - tut.‘ i "a .14 ...: ‘w H 'I‘. .: .1 \ ~‘E 83 labor force outside of unions. This latter group includes the several million service employees whose wages are be- low the federal minimum while the former group encompasses much of the under class of big cities: recent rural mi- grants, the aged, racial minorities (Gorz, 1971:23). Much of the work force organized into small unions such as the United Paperworkers can be found here also. The multinationals of the monOpoly sector plan the future and through their peak associations-~the Committee for Economic Development, the Business Counci1-—argue for the advantages of foreign investment, trade liberalization, and, in times of intensified international competition, the need to increase productivity. Businesses in the competi- tive sector struggle to survive from year to year and, when their representatives speak politically, it is in the terms _of tariff protection to save jobs and businesses at home and ' the demand that big government and big labor give the small guy "just trying to make an honest buck" a break. For most of the several hundred thousand people of this country who experience mobility from the ranks of the employed to the ranks of the self employed--and usually back again--during their lifetime, this sector is the setting for the dream of economic independence. That is to say they become de- pendent on the market (monopoly sector companies subsume the market) rather than on an employer. No magazines celebrate life in this sector. It is in- visible in the manner of Harrington's The Other America, of .0. Q‘" 5“ I... v 0. h I. u- ‘I-l '9... W. ‘ ‘I. a ..A. 84 which much of it forms a part. Our freeways go around it, or if through it, the competitive sector is shoved aside first. Hosiery mills, drug stores, laundries--the jobs, the industries, and even the people seem a grab bag. Never- theless, again something can be said about characteristics and trends. Capital per employee is low and productivity is neither high to begin with nor rising very rapidly, lagging behind the growth of productivity in the economy as a whole. Wages are also low. These jobs are often beyond the reach of federal minimum wage laws and wages are largely market determined, rising no faster than the rate of infla- tion. Labor demand is often unstable in any given firm or industry but overall the labor demand in this sector grows faster than that of the monopoly sector. Working conditions are poor, barely meeting and sometimes violating minimum . _standards of—noise, ventilation, and cleanliness. All of 'these are characteristics we might associate with the brutal squeezing of a work force in a drive for higher profits. The work force is squeezed alright, but the high profits are not there. Profit rates are lower than in the monopoly sector nor can they be increased and wages and working con- ditions improved. The competitive sector is already over- crowded and price increases simple shift demand away from one easily substitutable good to another. Thus, the working poor, more than 50 percent of the total poor, are here and a good portion of the aged poor spent much of their working years here. These are also the jobs available to those who 85 move in and out of officially defined poverty and on and off the welfare rolls. Finally, while O'Connor's original formulation implied that an industry would usually be located in one sector or another, what we actually find is that many industries cut across both sectors. Copper is a good example of this pat- tern. On the one hand, there is big copper-~Anaconda, Kennecott, and Phelps Dodge--which together produce two- thirds of U.S. mine output. On the other hand, there are the 175 or so companies which work the approximately 200 xnines that provide 5-6 percent of U.S. copper output. While my discussion of cepper focuses on the big three, with oc- casional interest in the middle level producers such as Nhgma or Miami, I shall also discuss the economic and po- litical role of the small producers whose world is that of the competitive sector. The new political economy of lib- ' eralism has attempted to incorporate both big and small business in the synthesis of state and economy. Copper as a Monopoly Sector Industry Company [Anaconda] and subsidiaries are en- gaged in the mining, milling, and smelting of nonferrous metal ores; in the refining and sale of the materials obtained from these ores; in the manufacture and distribution of semi-finished and finished COpper, aluminum, and brass products, and lumber. The principal metals recovered from ores treated are copper, lead, and zinc, but there are also recovered silver, gold, arsenic, cadmium, manganese, selenium, and tellurium...At Great Falls, Montana, company owns an electrolytic re- finery...Company owns lumber mills at Bonner, Montana, with a capacity of about 114,000,000 board feet per annum...At Butte, Montana, a . .l'... s “ .“uO ‘f 0“: 000% o “n. .l 4. it. I I‘. . ‘QA' . ““9v8-n ' a "An . _ ‘sfiwl .;‘: 3‘ ‘x.‘ " J l' ‘I~. “..E NA. I» ““9. F ‘Nv' : Pa... ‘ c o...' 9‘ .0 o ‘ -'-.._: g v a‘_‘. In ‘:t A“, "v. ‘ 'I :u i 86 subsidiary, the Butte Water Co., Operates the water system... ---Moody's Industrial Manual, 1965 During the post war years, approximately 200 companies have been activein copper mining in the United States. As suggested above, three of these stand head and shoulders above the rest. But their superior position in c0pper mining alone does not begin to exhaust the power and scope of Anaconda, Kennecott, and Phelps Dodge. Before it can be utilized in the production of other goods, copper has to be refined and fabricated. Twelve companies constitute the entire copper refining industry in the U.S. Four of these control 88 percent of total refining capacity: ASARCO 24 percent, Phelps Dodge 23 percent, Kennecott 21 percent, Anaconda 20 percent. In the refining stage, which requires a much larger commitment of capital than mining, the depen- H-dency of the small nonintegrated producers on big copper is 'readily apparent. *It is here that big COpper also jostles Ione another: Kennecott's long time stock and buyer/seller ties to ASARCO have linked a major producer with a company whose copper interests were based at the refining stage. As ASARCO has used state aid to integrate backwards, Kennecott ins acquired its own refining capacity. Finally, Anaconda, Kennecott, and Phelps Dodge are three of the four firms that Inssess 50 percent of the nation's fabricating capacity (Report of the Subcommittee, 1970:12; Wideman, 1965:266). It is immediately obvious that big copper, like other monOp- Oly sector industries, is characterized by a high degree of 87 vertical integration. Or, in the words of Anaconda's sales department: "From the Mine to the Consumer." As Robert Engler points out in his brilliant Politics of Oil, corporations of this nature and spread are as much political as economic organizations. They are best concep- tualized as competing and cooperating governments, each dedicated to bringing as much of the total industrial pro- cess as possible into the realm Of the predictable. That is to say that they desire to turn the external unknowns of the market into internal decisions of the firm. They are, in short, organized systems of power (Engler, 1961:3). In the financial, geographic, and personal scale of the deci- sions involved they rival many of the formal political en- tities with which they deal. As far as intra-industry politics and economics are concerned, the significance of .._the vertical-integration Of big copper can be summarized as follows. The political interests of big copper are consid- 'erably more diverse than those of competitive copper. At times,as I shall demonstrate in Chapters Four and Five, big COpper and competitive COpper Oppose each other. At the same time, the integrated producers are less vulnerable to the ups and downs of the economic cycle. They may have good and bad years but they continue to have those years. Many of the smaller producers close down or operate at a loss during periods of slack demand. Just as the big three are the major miners, refiners, and fabricators of copper, so they are the visible element a... 1 ..‘J A ‘0‘ Fl ...ov. a ‘0'”! a. on. —--.C« 0.. . .. ‘ u ‘0.- 0;: III . n b H ‘ 88 of the industry. All have been among the 175 largest cor- porations by sales in the Fortune 500 since that yearly hymn to bigness in business was first published in 1954. The TNEC included the companies in their list of the 200 largest nonfinancial corporations in the late 1930's. On an asset basis they are even larger. Anaconda and Kennecott are among the 100 largest on the Fortune list and Phelps Dodge is in the next 25. The consistency of rank among the three demonstrates the stability of the monopoly sector--while they have moved up and down on Fortune's list, it has always been 1, 2, 3--Anaconda, Kennecott, Phelps Dodge. In fact, the pattern of stability is even longer. Since 1912, Anaconda and Kennecott (or their corporate ancestors) have been the two leading COpper producers in the capitalist world with Phelps Dodge usually third or fourth (Herfindahl, ._1959:171) . ~ - Copper itself has been a visible metal. One of the 'first to be mined and used in human society, it formed the basis of the bronze age in the past and is the basic metal in the age of electricity in the present. Since the indus- trial revolution, only one metal, iron, has been removed from the earth in greater quantities than the red metal. Copper remained the second metal in world output until the 1960's when aluminum, a much newer and partially competitive substance, passed it in terms of yearly production (Ageton and Greenspoon, 1970:535-537). Finally, as big capital is entrenched in the corporate organization of the industry, 89 so the labor force is in the domain of one of the largest unions, the United Steelworkers. Unlike some monopoly sec- tor industries, the consolidation on the side of labor is late and still incomplete. Other unions such as the United Mine Workers still have a hold in the industry and until the late 1960's no one union was dominant. The International Union of Mine, Mill, and Smelter Workers (IUMMSW), expelled from the C10 in the late 1940's for its refusal to purge alleged communists from leadership positions, held the largest number of contracts in the industry until the end of the 1950's. After the explusion, the USW, apparently with industry encouragement, made repeated raids on IUMMSW contracts. While the outcome of the conflict was a stale- mate--IUMMSW held most of its existing contracts but failed to expand with the industry-~the financial exhaustion of the smaller-union made it a willing recipient of USW merger 'feelers during 1966-1967. The merger talks culminated with the dissolution of the IUMMSW in the U.S. and its absorption by the USW in 1967 (gggg, 1946-1967). Table 1 on the following page compares big copper with a sample of other large corporations, the mining and manu- facturing concerns of the Fortune 500.1 Most, and probably all, of the latter group of companies would also be part of the monopoly sector. Thus, the comparison is between big copper and a sample of monopoly sector corporations. Sev- eral relationships which emerged in the course of the theo- retical discussion of the monopoly sector are readily s 90 Table 1. Selected Data on Sales, Assets, Employees, and Invested Capital, Big Copper and Fortune 500: 1954-1969 1.91514. Sales Asset Employees Rank Rank Rank Assets/Employee Sales/Employee Anaconda 62 22 37 $22,427 11,882 Kennecott 71 25 , 64 28,692 16,629 Phelps Dodge 108 68 123‘ 26,250 20,194 Fortune 500, median --— --- --- n.a. n.a. 1959 Sales Asset Employees SaleS/s Assets/ Sales/ Rank Rank Rank Invested Capital Employee Employee Anaconda 69 25 53 $0.69 $28,508 $16,696 Kennecott 98 47 75 0.58 29,481 16,055 Phelps Dodge 161 89 144 0.75 29,560 20,245 Fortune 500, =*3 median --- --- --- 2.06 14,849 20,054 1964 Sales Asset Employees Sales/S Assets/ Sales/ Rank Rank Rank Invested Capital Employee Employee Anaconda 61 31 49 $0.84 $30,019 $21,064 Kennecott 116 52 95 0.69 35,073 20,918 Phelps Dodge 156 101 168 0.90 33,553 26,956 Fortune 500, ,u3 median --- --- --- 2.14 16,957 23,162 1969 Sales Asset Employees Sales/S Assets/ Sales/ Rank Rank Rank Invested Capital Employee Employee Anaconda 76 45 74 $1.21 $40,343 $32,266 Kennecott 111 52 143 0.95 57,183 36,341 Phelps Dodge 168 122 212 1.14 44,829 37,133 Fortune 500, 3.3” median --- --- —-— 2.41 21,545 27,986 Source: Computed from relevant issues of Fortune magazine 1955, 1960, 1965, 1970. 91 apparent for big copper. First, even within a group of firms with higher than average assets per employee, a mea- sure of capital intensity, big copper stands well above the median in each year (inspection of the 1954 data for indi- vidual companies makes clear that the same relationship holds then also). Second, sales per employee moves from at or below the median in the early years Of the period to a position above the median by 1969. This is an indication that, again relative to the Fortune 500 sample of monopoly sector corporations, big copper grows more through increased productivity than through growth in employment. Third, be- cause of the heavy capital commitments indicated by these first two measures, sales per dollar of invested capital are well below the median for the entire group. Overall, mining showed the lowest value of sales per dollar of in- ._vested capital and ranked among the four highest industries 'in terms of sales and asset value per employee in each of ithe years for which that information is available. Last but not least, profits as a rate of return of sales, both for mining and for big copper, exceed the median even for the 500 in each year, a further indication of the function and structure of big COpper as a monOpoly sector industry. Table 2 on page 93 compares growth trends for big cop- per and the U.S. economy during the same decade and a half. The dollar value increase in output for big copper grew at about the same rate as the GNP indicating the fairly slow growth of demand in monopoly sector industries. The A“ a:"' .‘yodca ('7' ~. ‘1‘:— '-l u w v—u - a...- Q -‘uu' -- -~n.a \ I.- abbnv u. “ ‘5.- c "0 - \ ~‘A \. ‘ 4“ C N‘.‘. '~ ~. w, 7‘» . "I ‘ 92 variation ranged only from Phelps Dodge's 8 percent less than GNP to Anaconda's 19 percent more than GNP. While it might seem desirable to control both GNP and sales for price changes, in the latter case this would be virtually impos- sible since the total sales of each company are composed of a changing mix of as many as twenty different metals. A rough measure of.what the actual relationship between sales growth in copper and GNP growth with prices controlled would be can be estimated as follows. The price of COpper, the largest single element in the total sales of each company, more than doubled between 1954 and 1969 while inflation during the same period was less than 75 percent. Thus, on a constant dollar basis for copper and the total GNP, the sales growth for the three companies was less than GNP growth, further demonstrating the slow growth in demand for .u_uwnopoly sector output. The comparison between increase in ”'employees and growth of the labor force strikingly demon- strates the inability of a monOpoly sector industry to ab- sorb new labor at the rate it becomes available. Both Anaconda and Kennecott increased employment at less than one-third the rate of growth of the private non-agricultural labor force despite a sales growth (for all products) which VHS greater than the dollar growth of output in the private sector of the economy. Even the much greater increase in employment by Phelps Dodge was not as large as the growth cm either the private or total non-agricultural labor force. Total employment in big copper expanded at less than half 93 the rate of growth of the non-agricultural civilian labor force. Once again this indicates the lagging rate of labor absorption in the monopoly industry, forcing increased mar- ginalization in the competitive sector and the growth of state employment. Table 2. Big COpper and the U.S. Economy 1954-1969 % In- % In- crease crease Private % In- % In- Non-agri. Non-ag. crease GNP crease Civilian Civilian in Increase in Em- Labor Labor Sales 1954-1964 ployees Force Force Anaconda 184.4 12.6 Kennecott 148.2 154.7% 13.3 43.4 39.4 Phelps Dodge 142.6 32.1 "n'Sources: Calculated from Economic Report of the President. 1972 and Fortune. In the remainder of this discussion of COpper as a monOpoly sector industry, I have had to make use of information com- ;filed for the entire industry and divided by size of estab- lishment. This is the form in which the Census of Manufac- tures and the Census of Mineral Industries provides data rather than by identifiable company. Thus, only an approx- imation of the relationship between big COpper and the rest of the economy is available although, at least at the mining stage, this approximation is very close. The largest mines are generally owned by the three largest corporations in the '00." .r. - O .. ...cau ' .-ooo ”- ~- .40“.| a ‘U .Q . “Ia. "‘O- 1..” 5... v .2 A. "'V . - '-~ .- (In a l I n f 94 industry. To some extent this same relationship holds in the refining and fabricating stages of the industry also although here the size differential is less marked. Perhaps the key relationship of the monOpoly/competitive division of the political economy is what Bluestone (1972a: 65) calls the secular deterioration of wages of competitive sector workers compared to monOpoly sector workers. Rather than divide the entire economy between competitive and mo- nopoly sectors, I have simply compared wages Of production workers in copper with those for all private nonagricultural workers. Table 3 presents this data for COpper mining and COpper rolling and drawing (fabricating). I had hoped to make three comparisons: (l) a comparison of wages for all production workers in each group; (2) a comparison between the wages of those workers in the largest copper establish- ..-ments (an approximation of big copper) and those of all 'private nonagricultural workers; and (3) to get at the question of monopoly and competitive sectors within the copper industry, a comparison of the hourly wages of the largest establishments with those of the smallest estab- lishments. However, except for the last Census Of Manufac- tures in 1967, the data necessary for the second and third comparison are not available for rolling and drawing. This has necessarily restricted the discussion, although mining employment is an important segment of the total employment, comprising more than half the employment in mining, milling, smelting, and refining. ‘S' v; ‘ '5. I ... “"9 .\'. ... "A. a ~.'.' I I. ‘ ' \ .._‘. a .. .‘1 . .‘. I. ' l . ~. ‘. a '~ :I 5.. .' ‘ ‘. ,K . P \i. . ...‘ ‘ ,“-~ .. ‘ .\.. ‘h a}: l ‘ .‘:‘: ‘6‘. 9S Table 3. The Secular Deterioration of Wages (All Ratios Involve Average Hourly Wage Rates of Production Workers) Ratio 1947 1950 1955 1960 1965 1972 Copper Mining/All Private Nonag. Wkrs. 1.15 1.17 1.24 .26 1.28 1.30 Copper Rolling & Drawing/ All Private Nonag. Wkrs. .19 1.23 .24 1.25 1.25 1.19 Ratio 1939 1954 1958 1963 1967 Copper Mining Estabs. With 1000+ Wkrs./ All Private Nonag. Wkrs. N.A. 1.31 1.38 1.43 1.41 Copper Rolling & Drawing Estabs. With 1000+ Wkrs./ All Private Nonag. Wkrs. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A 1.28 Copper Mining Estabs. With 1000+ Wkrs./ Copper Mining Estabs. .,__With4100 Wkrs. 1.08 1.20 1.19 1.23 1.28 "Copper Rolling &.Drawing Estabs. With 1000+ Wkrs./ Copper Rolling & Drawing Estabs. With<100 Wkrs. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. 1.10 sources : Ratios calculated from Employment & Earnings: United States 1909-71, U.S. Dept. Of Commerce, n.d.; Employment & Earnings, December 1973; 1939, 1954, 1958, 1963, and 1967; Census of Manufac- tures, Industry_Statistics: Nonferrous Metals, Mill and Foundrprroducts and Census of Mineral Industries, General Summary and Industry Sta- tistics: Copper, Lead, Zinc, Gold and Silver Ores. r-O- It; Ia rule the t 1.33. hi V n n o-‘opceb hood D :;-‘.'DDS ' ~-'vt»u n P‘. ‘z' .09 o F ‘ - ‘2' an. . .. u- a. .‘5 - V ‘V M. ‘3 . .“n . fix.“ '2‘ cu»...‘ . '1. I 3.3” ‘ v ..'."‘.a ‘- ... . ~. -.‘:L‘ . Ii.‘u'. I In.’ 96 The ratios in Table 3 for COpper mining strongly sup- port the theory of uneven development and secular deterio- ration of wages between monOpoly and competitive sector industries. The relative gap between wages in copper mining and all other private nonagricultural production employees has increased during each period although not at a steady rate. The largest relative gains were made during the Kor- ean War but the trend may not have been wartime induced since it was not repeated during the Vietnam War. It would be fascinating to have a similar ratio for the late 1930's to determine the significance of the New Deal/WWII era for the establishment of this pattern but no data for average hourly earnings in the entire economy are available for these years. The ratios between the wage rates in the. largest mines and those for the entire economy reinforce the concept.of secular deterioration of wages and demonstrate 'the existence of,a monopoly sector within the COpper indus- try. This analysis is reinforced from a different angle by the ratios between wages in large and small establishments within the industry. The intra-industry secular deteriora- tion of wages is almost as marked as that between COpper and the rest of the economy. On this measure, 1939 data is available and the 1939/1954 figures lend support to the argument for the consolidation of the social relations of uneven development during the 1940's. Copper fabricating exhibited the lowest level of con- centration within the industry, a factor which may account I..- ..-v u“-- .---u . mv. '9 a. J. ,y .H o o o -‘ ‘ "o C all (I 97 for the mixed results for this industry on the question of secular deterioration of wages. On the one hand, the indus- try emerges as a relatively high paid one, with a larger industry/total private economy gap in the initial year than was true for copper mining. Once again the early 1950's show the largest secular deterioration and the ratios keep pace with those for copper mining until 1960. However, during the 1960-1972 period the wage gap first levels and then actually declines between 1965 and 1972. As noted pre- viously, it is not possible to calculate comparisons by size for copper rolling and drawing except for 1967. Using the latter year as a benchmark, it appears that the differentia- tion between monopoly and competitive sector industry is much less pronounced here than in the case of copper mining with a ratio of 1.10 for the wage gap between large and - -small establishments in the former case compared to 1.28 in 'the latter. It should be reiterated that these statistics Rare only by size of establishment, not by individual com- pany. Information on the fabricating plants of big COpper might lend stronger support to the secular deterioration of wages argument. Data pertaining to several of the other dimensions of monopoly sector industries are presented in Table 4. Demand for copper rose at less than the rate of GNP growth, largely due to the concentration of end use in the producer goods industries and to increased efficiency in raw material us- age. The price inelasticity of demand for monOpoly sector 98 Table 4. Labor and Product Demand, Copper and the U.S. Economy I. Index Numbers of GNP (Constant Dollars), Gross Private Domestic Investment (Constant Dollars) and Copper Mine Production, 1947-1971 (1947 = 100) 1947 1950 1955 1960 1965 1971 GNP 100.0 114.6 141.3 157.4 199.4 238.6 Copper Mine Production 100.0 107.3 117.8 127.4 159.5 179.6 Price per Pound of Refined COpper 100.0 99.5 178.5 154.1 168.4 248.8 II. Index Numbers of Employment of all Wage and Salary Workers (1947 = 100) 1947 1950 1955 1960 1965 1971_ Civilian Non-ag. Labor Force 100.0 103.1 115.5 123.6 138.6 161.1 Private Non-ag. Labor Force 100.0 101.8 111.1 114.1 125.4 142.6 Employment in \ , COpper Mining- 100.0 92.7 99.2 91.5 100.0 123.9 (1953 = 100) .~~‘ 1958 1960 1965 1971 Private Non-ag. Labor Force 100.0 105.2 115.6 131.5 Employment in Copper Rolling and Drawing 100.0 97.8 99.7 88.0 Sources: Calculated from Employment & Earnings: United - States 1909-71, U.S. Dept. of Commerce, n.d.; Employment & Earnings, December 1973; Economic Report of the President, 1972; Minerals Yearbook, annual. .. ..uo" “'0'-“ . I h. .' N V- '3; av I—ov ‘- s-n-uA '5‘ . ~ I dun.» be ' . in! nu.) 0.0.: ‘ . ‘. c“, 5“, “"9 cl- - ‘l~. .| V : ‘ua... .. Va ‘ ' .. :v a o... ‘.H‘ 1 1-.' o."- .. .. "P. - . It» 1 I (I “I 99 commodities is also indicated by a comparison of the index numbers of copper output and COpper prices. The indices for the growth of employment graphically indicate the failure of monopoly capital to absorb new labor in line with the rate of labor force growth in even the pri- vate economy. When the comparison is with the total non- agricultural labor force, the short fall in employment ex- pansion is even greater since it is the state--federa1, state, and local--which has been the greatest absorber of new labor in the last three decades. Particularly illumi- nating would be a comparison between growth in employment in copper production alone among the big three of the in- dustry and total civilian employment. Unfortunately this comparison cannot be made because the post WWII period has witnessed diversification and conglomeration on the part of big copper.--For example, even by the middle fifties, — Anaconda's combined output Of all other metals--lead, zinc, gold, silver, molybdenum, etc.--exceeded her output of cop- per. The same mining and processing facilities are usually the source of a variety of metals, thus making employment calculations by particular metal impossible. An insight into the significance of this development-- conglomeration--can be obtained by contrasting the employ- ment expansion figures for big COpper from Table 2 with those for copper mining, COpper rolling and drawing, and the total economy in Table 4. Employment has grown faster .in big copper than in the COpper industry as a whole despite O'V'. _, a an...- 1.. o I}! v- ‘- ‘vh a..- Q ‘~‘ ‘ *‘ 100 the greater productivity of the former, although the total labor force has grown even faster. The thrust towards con- glomeration thus appears to be quite important for big COp- per in terms of employment expansion, a pattern that is probably characteristic of monopoly industry as a whole. This is a major counter trend to the marginalization of more and more of the labor force into the competitive sector and is realized through the concentration and centralization of capital. As a conclusion to this discussion of the structure and growth trends of copper as a monopoly sector industry, one more facet of monopoly industry must be noted, the inter- nationalization of capital. For copper, this process con- siderably predates the post WWII era. Anaconda acquired and brought into production its Chilean, Mexican, and . , (former) Polish properties before the Great Crash. Kennecott " developed itsChilean mine during the same years. Phelps Dodge, which remains a primarily domestic producer, had not gone offshore before the end of WWII. Nonetheless, the shift of the U.S. from a net exporter to a net importer of raw materials in 1940 was also true of copper production and consumption (Bidwell, 1958:l). Since that time, this Country has consumed approximately a third of capitalist World copper output while producing about a quarter of this total (Coppg, various issues; Wideman, 1965:293). Coupled With this shift in the trade balance has been a declining grade of ore, "one of the most significant factors affecting cnpper production cost" (Ageton and Greenspoon, 1970:546) . .1“; .09 , out O‘- In "(3 r1 r'nfafl L‘V AHLCI 8‘? -:':‘;’* ‘ s .Ivruuiv O ;~:v- p; f II'O.‘ Vb b 4....13, “ .- pi .iu'v. ~:P,n-~n C Influ: 0L w~fn A: h, "‘:-' ‘4'. y: . a... g"- " A --0v.n‘ 21‘ as fol V , H. . .H.:ID 7' a. ' VA. 1.. P" ”F "'.“n. J '4‘. .2... aCCEi C II I f 4 101 The response of big COpper to this crisis was concisely summarized by Kennecott in its 1951 Annual Report: "Your management is making every effort in the three of the four quarters of the globe where exploration is possible, to find amidevelop new mines" (Kennecott COpper Corporation, 1951). Nuzfocus of this chapter is not the international political emonomy of COpper. Thus, for present purposes the dialectic of national monopoly/international expansion can be summa— rized as follows: MOnopoly industries at home are able to accumulate the necessary capital to expand abroad; success- ful foreign expansion means control over foreign resources, direct access to foreign markets, geographical dispersion ” of political risks, and the multiplication of financial op- portunities (compare Girvan, 1971a:24-37). In turn, these serve to reinforce monopoly power at home. In this process .-as in the process of domestic growth and conglomeration, 'the relationship-between big copper and the state has been fundamental. It is to an analysis of the state in the metropole political economy that I now turn. The Kapitalistate as Instrument and Structure Well, I do not think that necessarily any organized effort in industry to bring about a stabilization of prices means necessarily a fixed price. I do think it would be infinitely better from the standpoint of employment, from the standpoint of the ownership, stockholders, man- agement, and everybody concerned, if we had some means of protecting the public and at the same time enabling industry to self regulate itself... --Cornelius F. Kelley, Pres. and Chmn. of Anaconda, testimony before the TNEC in January 1940 ‘— 0!; fa . \r v» hst'fir 7' “a l I b vul- ,..,.~. . “Io-i; ‘ {‘o . \ «L. ‘v. -' o (D C) 0h In t) I 11‘ o 2 102 We cannot go through another ten years like the ten) years at the end of the twenties and the begiruiing of the thirties without having the most farreaching consequences upon our economic and social system. --Sec. of State Dean Acheson, statement before the Congressional Committee on Postwar Economic Policy in November 1944 From the onset of the capitalist era, politics and the political authority have been integral to the creation of a V' 3'...“- fertile soil for the expansion Of capital. Politics and z. 2: economics were inextricably mingled in the West European city states which were the birthplace of the modern bour- geoisie (Dobb, 1963:Chapter 5; Pirenne, 1956). The mercan- tilism that followed was simply the city policy writ large (Cox, 1959:318ff). Even the theoretical father of laissez faire recognized an important role for the state. 'After all, Adam Smith did want the political authority to do cer- Uftain things; -to remove the fetters Of the mercantile order and to clarify and enforce the rules of the game for the new regime of competition. Capital would do the rest. In the laissez faire capitalist order, the state acts as an instrument rather than as a structure. This instru- ment is wielded in the interest of capital as a whole and tithe maintenance of the class structure which is its basis enm.which capital itself reproduces (Sweezy, 1968:240-244). (Attfimes, of course, the state acts in the narrow interests Ofindividual capitalists but we are not concerned with this vmfiation in the rules of the game here. Anyway, such ac- tnm is usually legitimated in terms of the broader framework ...~Ars I o ”..vu M A ' U us‘ ‘..oa a' “to. O ‘_v‘; A“ .. " Vu . . :F‘-.' v‘,‘. " 'h 'u D U.“ p- H“. . x'fi‘v d , 1 'u C . ‘s 1‘»; VGA 0 Vi 103 of actions necessary to maintain the capitalist social order.) Of paramount importance is the definition by the political authority of an industry, region, or project as Open to private capital accumulation, the guaranteeing of the right of private property (Murray, 1971:88; Miliband, 1969:69ff). For mining corporations, themselves a product of this guarantee, the nature of the market in land is the all important question. In the words Of a contemporary spokesman of big copper, the demand Of capital is for the following: (1) security Of tenure; (2) exclusivity of use; and (3) the setting of the Operating rules (EQMJ, February 1969:124, speech by Kennecott's General Counsel Malcolm R. Wilkey on the question Of access to underwater minerals). Security of tenure does two things. First, it provides the time horizon necessary for large scale investment to be -, made. Whenlprofits can be reasonably anticipated next year and next decade,_the firm can use this year to build the 'required infrastructure, train the necessary labor force, and carry out the research demanded by the project. Second, security Of tenure is important in the intercorporate strug- gle over control Of mineral resources. A competitor cannot acquire the land worked by one firm today for its own use tomorrow. Exclusivity of use complements security of ten- Ure. Since usage is exclusive, others cannot reap the external economies which are the potential result of a trans— portation network, a power source, or the technical knowl- edge acquired by the first occupant. Exclusive and secure Q .0- :‘I “ a I" L: a. .U \v I Q I‘VEF: a“ lib...‘ ad 1 b"- i :25: . ul-v:o’ A“ n.a.doodlbl . ‘0'! III- HF.‘ _.. n. u,‘ "w. ‘R A: "'§‘: J; foo : ru‘ '-.... . ‘1 ’d 2...- I? ‘ “'"Vnos r “)3. fin ' bony U5 .2. A t . a as H§. ‘ on; 1"} A; n "r 4.5%} U “ . § ._ ,1 ‘..N I \~‘. F‘ “J- I“ a \ 5,:1 ~ a; {1. “\ l.’ 1.3“ . .y \‘ Ii ‘ a. .5": “1‘ ‘ 104 usage and access together mean that after a mineral deposit is purchased it can be developed at a time and output set at a rate that makes the most economic sense for a given corporation. All of this can be done without the fear that someone else will have removed all or part Of the deposit in the meantime on a schedule that fits their own differing calculus of private rationality. Finally, the state must set the rules of Operation. What is desired here is that the actions of the State be predictable enough to be entered into the cost accounting framework of the individual corpor- ation. A tax on profits, even a high one, is one thing; a tax on profits one year, on invested capital the next, a demand for a portion of the output the third, is something else. The latter is repugnant to capital which demands that the rules be made clear and not be subject to change without _notice. When-security Of tenure, exclusivity of use, and 'clarity of operating rules are integrated in the framework of the modern corporation, the vagaries of the market which dominate both small capital and those who must sell their labor power, are largely subsumed (see Galbraith, 1967:Chap- ters 3 and 6 for a discussion of the corporation's ability to subordinate the market). All of this is part of the generally taken-for-granted Scheme of things. In recent years, analyses of state and Capital during the monopoly phase have extended the argument, however. Increasingly the two are seen as coequals, what- ever the perspective Of the particular writer (compare Bell, ". ‘HMAV 01' yUo wad-:5 . ......J v - t‘lO‘V L‘ . . nuvof n- a "PV‘O‘ A . .u..‘..U . . .3, “5 ‘I... ma" ""vo A. a '01-.“. . s . :‘zo: ' 'I--. 1",": U...“ “ 105 1973; O'Connor, 1974; Shonfield, 1969). Both Robert Engler and Michael Tanzer, in their pathbreaking works on the Oil industry have stressed the political nature Of the modern corporation and the economic significance of all state ac- tion (Engler, 1961:3ff; Tanzer, 1970:20ff). Rather than the earlier model of the state as referee, a function that was appropriate for the period of Laissez faire, it is the posi- tive state that now occupies the stage. Murray (1971:88-91) has elaborated this line Of argu- ment in an article which suggests five functions of the kap- italistate in addition to its role as guarantor of property rights. (1) Economic liberalization consists largely of the abolition of pre-existing restrictions on the movement Of capital, labor, and commodities. The standardization Of currency, laws of trade, weights, etc. falls here also. _Within the national domains of the capitalist metropoles 'this task has long been accomplished (Cox, 1959). Today, as I shall argue later, it is the internationalisation Of capital which demands parallel efforts. (2) Economic or- chestration is the lesson of the Great Crash. The state attempts to regulate and lessen the ups and downs of the business cycle through some form of planning (Dowd, 1974: 269-271; Shonfield, 1969). This function belongs to the Positive state of the twentieth century while that of eco- nomic liberalization is also done by the state as referee of the nineteenth century. (3) Input provision in the form of labor, capital, land, and infrastructure has characterized “3;, 106 the kapitalistate from an early date. This has been par- ticularly the case in frontier areas such as the U.S. Here the state must regulate the supply and price of labor, de- fine both land and labor as alienable commodities, and sup- port the development and extension of a reliable system of finance and credit. In the U.S., state constant capital in- vestment in infrastructure has been important first in the system of canals of the late eighteenth/early nineteenth centuries, later the land for railroads in the nineteenth century, and finally the constructure of highways in the twentieth century (Faulkner, 1960:270ff, 428ff, and 622ff). In the monopoly phase, science has been harnessed to the logic of private profit and technical and scientific knowl- edge have come to the fore as state inputs. The rhythm of technological advance must be integrated with the rhythm of .- the business cycle. (4) Intervention for social consensus: 'the state attempts to meliorate the outcomes of the tempo of uneven deve10pment as it is manifested in the clash Of social and private rationality. Control of the external diseconomies of pollution and regional inequality, the reg- ulation of the conditions of work and of the functioning of the market place, and the effort to cushion the insecurity of employment and income for the underlying population, are all included here. (5) Finally, there is the problem of the external relations of a given national capitalism. Here the identity of the state with "its own" capital is perhaps the strongest. Aid, trade, and military policies, even when fl C.." V on- F" . O" an H‘- ,.... fl ...~.$ v --;: 5 -- -~ b . r-n an . ‘ -- -u- q IA' ‘b. ;- a...- 'k h u." o.._ ‘ '1 . . ‘ 5'1. .. .‘L. . -. ‘h \“ Q“ '4 ._.. ‘1 . I . . u I * ~ ‘ N: . \ ‘t . n‘ ‘ N o.‘ z ‘ . D“ . . “ ‘- o 107 carried out through "international agencies" are oriented to the need to provide a fertile soil for the international- ization of capital in a world of competing nation states (Magdoff, 1969: Hayter, 1971). At the same time, the state strives to protect the preserves that capital has already carved out at home and abroad. For the U.S. case, these functions of the state have been nicely encapsulated in Gabriel Kolko's notion of polit- ical capitalism, a formulation which rejects the dichotomy between the economy and the polity which has informed much historical and sociological analysis. He is worth quoting at some length: Political capitalism is the utilization of political outlets to attain conditions of stability, predictability, and security--to attain rationalization in the eco- nomy. Stability is the elimination of internecine competition and erratic fluctuations in the eco- nomy. Predictability is the ability, on the basis of-politically stabilized and secured means, to plan future economic action on the basis Of fairly calculable expectations...security...means protection from the political attacks latent in any formally democratic structure..rationaliza- tion...is the organization of the economy and the larger political and social spheres in a manner that will allow corporations to function in a predictable and secure environment permitting reasonable profits over the long run (Kolko, 1963: 3). The question then, is not state intervention or no state intervention, but what kind of state action by what agency and with what effects (Kolko, 1963:4). The transition from the state as instrument to the state as structure was contemporaneous with a shift in the ideological framework within which the dialectic of state ., ‘0 108 tal moved. While liberalism has been the hegemonic (Gramsci, 1971; the concept of hegemony in this been quite helpful throughout this section) of both nd then dominant business groups in the United two periods in the formation of the liberal politi- Dmic world view can be distinguished (Weinstein, i). The opening years of the twentieth century mark sition between these periods. In the nineteenth Weinstein sees equality, mobility, and antagonism nment intervention in the self-regulating political as the main tenets Of liberal doctrine. The con- On of big capital and the rise Of the U.S. as a ternational capitalist power in the early twentieth (Dowd, 1974:64-69, 85-87; Williams 1966:343ff) turning away from this emphasis on competition and a1 striving. In its place there was created a chauung of cOOperation, efficiency, and "social bility" (Sklar, 1972:22; Weinstein, l968:xiii). hegemonic task of the kapitalistate is the replace- the ideological concepts Of laissez faire capitalism ideal of a responsible social order in which all could look forward to some form of recognition and in the benefits Of an ever-expanding economy" in, 1968:x). The key element in the new order is ise of "an ever—expanding economy" such that op- al groups can always, given time, be incorporated established political economy. The roots of the '1"..- 9‘.‘ \< if 109 ever-expanding economy lie, of course, in the synthesis be- tween the monopoly sector and the state. It is upon this structure that the "socially responsible" community is built. (For an analysis of the crisis of the liberal conception Of the community see Wolff, 1969.) Much of the groundwork for this new structure of state and capital had been laid by the time of World War I. How— ever, prosperity and "the return to normalcy" Of the 1920's witnessed the temporary, and partial, suspension2 of these efforts (Bernstein,1969:265; Sklar, 1972:65; Williams 1966: 439ff). The impact of the Crash was to revive the thrust towards the new liberalism. This revival was essentially a return to a Wilsonian conception of the corporation, its role in the new industrial order, and its relationship to the state (Sklar, 1972:65). As Wilson had argued, the re- .-_sponse to the-new conditions could not be a return to a ' competitive capitalist order (he never seriously entertained .the possibility of a socialist alternative). Instead, the ef- fort Of the state must be directed towards preventing the misuse of the corporation and to redirect its functioning in the pursuit of the public interest (Sklar, 1972:19). Business and businessmen, while to be chastized if they violated the public trust or enriched themselves at the expense of the public interest, must not be subject to ar- bitrary and capricious executive decision making. They would also have to be adequately protected from the "polit- ical attacks latent in any formally democratic structure," '1 110 i.e., from the "whims" of popular Opinion as reflected in the elected bodies of government. Law, then, must create a predictable and secure environment for the flourishing of the new capitalism, for it was only in such an environment that the public good could be realized by private capital. Regulatory agencies provided the ideal solution. These agencies were to be charged with the dual task of preventing the abuse of the power of the corporation and encouraging the development of its public service potential. Each Of these tasks required the independence Of the regulators from both the executive and congress (Kolko, 1963:298; Sklar, 1972:20). This merger Of businessman and public Official (Wein- stein, 1968:10) was expressed well by Cornelius F. Kelley, president and board chairman of Anaconda, at the end of the ,,, depression.-.Ref1ecting on the experience of the depression ‘and the efforts of the New Deal to reconstruct the politi- cal ecOnomy of modern liberalism he asked that the TNEC agree to the proposition that industrial cooperation for stabilization be accepted as a protection and service to employees, owners, stockholders, and the general public. In sum, to ”everybody concerned," for all would then be able to participate in the benefits of the ever expanding eco- nomy (TNEC, 1941:13160). The voice of the industry, EgMJ, had reached the same conclusion nine years earlier in an editorial entitled "Uncontrolled Individualism and Its Aftermath" which attacked the arguments for free competitive determination of COpper prices on the grounds of humanitar- L- 'o. <1 ‘1 (I 111 ianism and the maintenance of local standards of living (£551! September 1931:241). As the quote from Secretary of State Dean Acheson at the head of this section indicates, businessmen were not alone in this realization and the stakes involved were recognized to be high indeed. In many ways this new vision was far from that of Adam Smith, yet the major flaw in each case is strikingly similar. Smith, with a background in moral philosophy, hoped to in- crease the scope of individual freedom and contribute to the common welfare by limiting the alien power of the state (Dowd, 1974:9-11). What he failed to see, and what Marx saw so clearly, was the manner in which his answer to the prob- lem produced a new alien, and even more awesome, power, the corporation in a Hobbesian capitalist world. The new lib- eralism created the other term in the dialectic, the state ,_w regulatory agency. Perhaps, from a movement that was not ’opposed to business but in fact often led by business (Kolko, 1963), the aufhebung was inevitable: the synthesis of state and capital in kapitalistate. A new and still more threatening structure emerged which has been the pivot of the political economy of U.S. capitalism during the last three decades. The functioning of this new synthesis, of the state as structure, is best understood through the marxian categories of social expenditure and social investment as developed in O'Connor's Fiscal Crisis of the State. It is in the changing volume and distribution of state expenditures that the po- litical economy of the state sector appears and it is these .ll 112 expenditures that reflect the two contradictory functions of the state: capital accumulation and social legitimation (O'Connor, 1974). Capital accumulation encompasses the pre- dictability and stability aspects of political capitalism while legitimation brings together Kolko's concern with security and Weinstein's larger emphasis on the legitimation of the corporate ideal in the liberal social order. Togeth— er they provide the anatomy Of contemporary U.S. capitalism. Let us look more concretely at the nature Of these two categories of state expenditure. State outlays that in- crease the tempo and amount of capital accumulation are geared towards the expansion, growth, and continued har- monious class relations in the monOpoly sector. This type of expenditure appears in the form Of social capital and can be further subdivided into expenditures for social con- sumption, or social variable capital, and those for social investment, or social constant capital. The former are designed to lower the costs of the reproduction Of labor power through investment in variable capital and include state financed and organized schemes such as social insur- ance and urban renewal. These expenditures decrease the proportion of the working day devoted to the reproduction of labor power thus increasing the time that can be devoted to the creation Of surplus value and raising the rate of ex- ploitation. Social investment as a category of social cap- ital can be further divided into physical capital such as transportation, industrial parks, and mineral exploration, | J. _r O ‘-4 113 and investment in human capital such as administrative and scientific training programs. Both forms of social invest- ment increase the productivity of labor through investment in constant capital. Thus, they enable capital to increase the relative rate of exploitation and the amount of surplus value extracted from a given amount Of labor power (see Marx, 1967:Vol. 1, Chapters XVII-XXVII on the relationship of surplus value, constant capital, variable capital, and rates of exploitation). Both types of social capital out- .fi-h lays are indirectly productive since they indirectly expand I ‘m I - surplus value, the sine qua non of productivity in the eyes W" .I' . .——'~ of capital. It is the reality of the productivity of state expen- diture in contemporary capitalism that can be taken as dis- tinguishing the state as structure from the state as instru- . _ment. The difference can be summarized as follows: S l. The State as Instrument: C+V+SF p ass 2. The State as Structure: (Cp+CS)+(Vp+VS)+(Sp+SS) where C=constant capital; V=variab1e capital; S=surplus value and the subscripts p and s indicate private and state sectors. In the former case the total constant and the total variable capital are equal to private constant and private variable capital. All state expenditures are financed out of surplus which is divided between private and state portions through political bargaining. The state and the private sector are thus in conflict over the distribution of the social surplus. 1.2;; 114 This model of the state and economy has underlaid much marxian analysis (cf Baran and Sweezy, 1966) and, although without this conceptual framework, much of the orthodox social science discussion of the state. Although the re- visionist historians have also not discussed the issue in these terms, they have in fact worked with the second model of state and economy. Here the state and private capital participate together in the investment of constant and vari- able capital. As it stands, this formulation is partially ‘“ misleading when it comes to the disposition of surplus value. Under the rules of the capitalist game, the state does not directly appropriate the surplus value which its outlays indirectly create but instead relies on taxation. This distinction is crucial for grasping the socialization of costs/private appropriation Of profits/fiscal crisis --n-dia1ectic. ‘ The very.process of state productive expenditure in the .monopoly sector creates the need for the contradictory state role of legitimation. Legitimation expenditures must re- integrate both the casualties of monopoly sector growth, i.e., the social disruption of the "ever-expanding economy," and meliorate the relative economic deprivation of competitive sector capital and labor. These expenditures appear as social expenses in the analysis of the state budget. They are not even indirectly productive, that is these outlays do not expand surplus value even indirectly. Unproductive should not here be equated with unnecessary for these 115 expenditures, like the outlays for the reproduction of labor power in Marx's schema, are "functional necessities" for the maintenance of the capitalist system. Welfare at home (Piven and Cloward, 1972) and counterinsurgency abroad (Klare, 1972) are examples. Although the categories social capital and social ex- penses interpenetrate each other (a point O'Connor, 1974, stresses:7) in conjunction with a graSp of the state as instrument they provide the essential framework for the analysis of the fusion of big COpper and the U.S. state. In what follows I attempt this analysis for the 1944-1973 period. I begin with a discussion Of the state as instru- ment and then move on to a more extensive examination of social expenses of legitimation which arise from the rhythm of capital accumulation on the part of big copper. . ’. l ’ .———~- .. V' ...— 116 NOTES 1 I have used 1969 as the last year in both Tables 1 and 2 since the rankings and ratios for the 1970-1973 period would be affected by the nationalization of COpper in Chile in 1971. This is particularly true for Anaconda which had dropped behind Kennecott in sales and assets in the 1973 rankings. The latter company's structure was also affected although not to the same degree. 2 The word suspension as it captures the relationship between the "return to normalcy" of the 1920's and the earlier elaboration of the political economy of modern lib- eralism has two contradictory senses. On the one hand it means to stop, to end, while on the other it means to sus- tain, to hold. Both of these senses are implied here, ' CHAPTER 3 AN ATTEMPT TO INTERNATIONALIZE THE NATIONAL RULES OF THE GAME: THE STATE AS INSTRUMENT The instrumental function of the kapitalistate falls under the normally accepted rules of the game. Few social theorists devote much time or effort to the consideration of the state as instrument of the capitalist class and busi- nessmen, while they certainly have a day to day awareness of these facts, do not write theoretical treatises. In it- self, the easy assumption of this reality is a tribute to the hegemony of the bourgeois social order. Nevertheless, n_it is worth summarizing the historical function of the U.S. "state as an instrument in the development Of the mining in- ydustry and the options excluded in the development Of a legal framework for mineral exploitation. This will enable us to see more clearly the meaning of efforts by big COpper, and big capital in general, to reproduce this pattern on the international level in the coming struggle for control over undersea mineral deposits. There are at least two patterns of mineral exploitation excluded by the capital/state relationship which have emerged in the U.S. The first pattern would have the state itself develop minerals such as copper, iron, and (later) aluminum 117 l 118 since these metals are necessary inputs in so many other industries. The model would be that of public utilities where a particular commodity is defined as a state input, a form of social constant capital. The state developed min- eral industry would have been Operated either at cost, thus decreasing the constant capital outlays of private capital, or to raise state revenue. The rate of profit but not the rate of surplus value would be increased in the former case. Pre-capitalist states such as Rome have Often pursued the latter course in an attempt to solve their own version of the fiscal crisis (Rostovtzeff, 1926:225). In either case, access to mineral supplies would have been Open to capital at large, limiting the possibility of preferred buyer/ seller relationships and generalizing both external eco- nomies and economies of scale. While state social constant ."_capital investment in mineral development would have fur- 'thered capital accumulation, it would have limited the con- ~tributiOn of minerals to unequal rates of accumulation, acting also as a counter to the tendency towards uneven de- velopment. Here the timing of the development of new de- posits, the setting of output levels, and the rate of depletion of old deposits would have differed from that of any individual corporation and from the simple sum of cor- porate decisions. This would also be true for the substi- tution of competing metals, e.g., COpper and aluminum, re- search priorities, and the calculus of social costs in mineral development. While for an earlier period this 119 pattern of mineral development may be considered marginal to the social structure of capitalism, it is certainly not incompatible with the thrust of capital for surplus value. The interests of private capital as a whole would be served as is the case with state industry in Western Europe (Kidron, 1970:Chapter l; Shonfield, 1969:Chapter 5; O'Connor, 1974:183-188). There is still a second pattern excluded by the U.S. case which is clearly within the capitalist rules of the game. In the areas of the world colonized by Spain and Portugual, particularly Latin America, the operating rules retained all of the subsoil and mineral rights as the pre- serve of the state. By and large, for both fiscal and ideological reasons, the state in these nations has not developed and operated these mineral deposits but has in- .stead leased.claim to individuals and firms for a specific period of time. ,The time involved has often been so long, 'e.g., §9 years, as to mean effective loss of state influ- ence. Nevertheless, this legal tradition has been the groundwork for state operated mining and petroleum companies in Latin nations (see Tanzer, 1970:Chapters 22 and 25 on state oil companies in Latin America). Rather than following either of these patterns, the U.S., reflecting its English colonial experience, followed the practice of Anglo-Saxon law. During the early years as an independent nation, the individual states provided the legal framework for mineral development. Both businesses 120 and markets were small and the differing state laws pre- sented no immediate problems. The boost given to regional and national business by the Civil War, the new technologies of large scale production, and the elaboration of a trans- portation network integrating previously disparate markets changed this, however (Faulkner, 1960:327ff and 477; Selig- man, 1971:91-112). Thus, by 1860 when the U.S. census showed a frontier area almost exactly equal to the already settled regions of the country, the expansion of capital re- quired the supersession of the conflicting legal frameworks of the individual states. Here mining led the way. "The search for minerals, which had played such a major role in the early exploration and settlement of the American conti- nent, again became an important influence..." (Faulkner, 1960:348). By 1890, the last frontier had been closed. The mineral-led development of these areas was based heavily on the legal framework established by the first {federal mining codes of 1866 and 1872. These codes con- tained two key provisions. First, corporations and indi- viduals were given free access to the public domain; second, low cost purchase--originally $5.00 an acre--was legislated for lode claims (McMahon, 1965:313). The codes were cast in the universalism characteristic of capitalist legal relations. The equally characteristic substantive inequality of capitalist society assured that it was to be yet another case where the effective rule was to be the famous dictum of Anatole France: "The law, in its majestic 121 equality forbids the rich as well as the poor to sleep under bridges, steal bread, or beg in the streets." All of this was of particular significance for copper since it was only a decade after the 1872 code that the first electric gen- erating stations were built in NYC, London, and Milan. Within another quarter century the automobile made its first appearance. The development of a mining code and the rise of the electrical industry transformed the composition of end use for copper and radically increased the volume of demand at a time when the states which were to dwarf the output of the then premier COpper district of the world-— Michigan--were being opened up to settlement. Each member of the triumvirate of big copper was established in the 1880-1910 period and each has found their richest domestic sources of copper in the five states of Arizona, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico, and Utah (Richter, 1927a). All of these were, of course, largely part of the public domain at the time of the first federal mining code and even today, when 20 percent of the contiguous U.S. is still within the public domain, fully 50 percent of these five states remain so sit- uated (United States, Dept. of Interior, l973:v-2). For big copper the framework established by these early state actiOns has been a profitable and generally smoothly working system for the last century. Now, however, a new game has begun and the stakes are high. By the early 1960's it was clear that the undersea mineral nodules (sometimes called manganese nodules) contained manganese, copper, iron, ‘ h’h _: wr- VIZ? 122 nickel, and cobalt to a total amount probably in excess of all that found on the dry land surface of the earth (see for example, the September 1959 E851 editorial "Who Owns the Sea?"). Thus, at a time when some minerals are ap- proaching absolute exhaustion in the U.S. and when the richest, most economical sources of many others are more likely to be found in the hinterlands of world capitalism, big capital is presented with a new opportunity for expan- sion. There is, however, a crucial problem. Most of the nodules are located in international waters. Does it follow that they should be "internationalized" minerals, in the development of which all nations shall participate? Big COpper, at least, has an answer to this query and the answer is no. Kennecott has been a leader among miner- al multinationals in the exploration of the ocean floor, beginning in 1967 to allocate substantial resources for such work (Kennecott Annual Reports). The U.S. state has been a coparticipant in this concern. In 1963 the United States Bureau of Mines (USBM) began a research program on the problems associated with metal and mineral mining under the ocean floor. During the same year the U.S. Geological Survey announced a five year study of the ocean floor (5251' February 1963:20 and May 1963:23). In 1967, the USBM undertook a program for underseas mining development in cooperation with private capital and the next year Senator Pell of Rhode Island proposed an Ocean Space Treaty while Kennecott began active prospecting on the Pacific floor fiifi' If": .lf 4 \ 123 (Eggg, February 1967:17 and July 1968:86). In 1969 the Marine Science Council, a state/capital group, issued a re- port urging that state agencies direct their energies to research on mineral extraction and mapping the ocean floor rather than on actual mining or the development of hardware for mining. The latter tasks were thought best left to pri— vate capital (gggg, January 1969:16). The next month Kennecott's General Council Malcolm R. Wilkey called for a new mining claims law for operations on the U.S. continental shelf, for defined boundaries between territorial and inter- national waters, and for provisions for activity on the part of private capital in the latter area. He went on to sug- gest that underseas minerals would become a significant component of world output in 7-10 years (Eéfllv February 1969: 124; Kennecott Annual Report, 1969). Later that year, the Assistant Secretary of the Interior for Mineral Resources, Hollis M. Dole, gave added impetus to this thrust by warning of a mineral shortage within twenty to thirty years which could depress the standards of living among the rich nations of the globe. Dole urged the need to develop foreign sources and new technology to tap unused mineral deposits (gggg, May 1969:15). Here the stategic concerns of the metropole state have come into play, providing support for but also acting inde- pendently of the private calculus of multinational mining capital (Girvan, 1971a:18-21 and 26-37, discusses the im- portance of metropole state strategic interests in the 124 determination of incremental mineral output and guaranteed access to supplies in the case of Jamaican bauxite). That is, a fusion of the state as instrument-~the efforts, de- tailed below, to define underseas mining as an area suitable for private capital accumulation--and the state as struc- ture-~social investment--is occurring. The concerns of the metropole state, as they have been manifested in internation- al debates and conferences over underseas mining, are three- fold. (1) Controlled access to underseas minerals, that is, access through the internationalization of nationally based capital, will provide assured supplies of these materials to meet future needs. This has been a recurrent concern of the U.S. state (Bidwell, 1958), first reflected in the Paley Report of 1952 and most recently expressed in the Annual Reports of the Secretary of the Interior under the 1970 Mining and Minerals Policy Act. (2) Underseas mineral re- sources could lessen the need of metropole nations. This concern is closely tied to the question of controlled and secure access. Here, underseas mineral deposits are per- ceived as providing a counter lever against rising third world nationalism. Would Chile, for example, have been as quick to nationalize U.S. copper investments--without com- pensation, no 1ess--if the threat of a Kennecott vice pres- ident to make Chile a "residual supplier" of the metal could have been realized through production from underseas mining? (3) Finally, the U.S-, along with Japan and sev- eral other capitalist metropoles are net importers of raw ”g “m C o _' m-O \~' I? 125 materials. This is a regular and rising negative entry in the balance of payments at a time when international compe- tition for both markets and raw materials is increasing sharply. (As early as 1965 the U.S. government was reported pressuring the mining industry to improve its balance of payments as reported in BEMJ, November 1965:23.) Underseas mining could alleviate this problem, giving the state greater freedom of action in the arena of international politics. (These three themes emerge from a reading of articles in mining publications such as Eéfll and Copper, newspaper accounts and the Reports of the Secretary of Interior issued under the 1970 Mining and Minerals Policy Act. See also the statement of C. H. Burgess, Kennecott vice president in Mineral Resources and the entire volume.) There are, however, other players in this game who have a different conception of what the appropriate rules are. Most of the smaller nations of the world are seeking UN control of mining under international waters and for a pooling of resources in the development of underseas min- eral deposits. The reason is simple: The cost of a single underseas mining operation is estimated at $300 million, a sum considerably beyond the reach of many smaller countries. International cooperation is desired also for deve10pment of technology and for market size sufficient to absorb the output from such a large investment. The possibility here is for an international rules of the game which would par- allel one of the patterns excluded in the U.S. case. The v. .- 77mfiv v v ' 126 [m could invest the social constant capital necessary to develop these resources and Operate them at cost or as a revenue source. In either case, the relative independence and the hopes for industrialization of hinterland nations would be increased. Both patterns would also increase the potential of the UN as a world government. This would be particularly true if the minerals were used to raise revenue, emancipating the UN financially from the political influence of the metropoles (cf Logue, 1973:405—418). The conflict over the future of mineral nodules has been joined on the floor Of the UN with the U.S. leading the Opposition to international control of underseas mining and, where outright opposition seems too politically costly; urging a go slow policy (EEMJ, March 1969:16). The third Law of the Sea Conference, in 1974, took up this issue but ”-was unable to-resolve it. Thus the conflict has been re- scheduled for future meetings. At present a stalemate exists between the political weight of the third world and the economic and military weight of the U.S. and a few metropole allies. The stand of the U.S.S.R., which could be crucial in the outcome, is still unclear. However, the mineral multinationals must be considered as another element in this conflict. It can- not be assumed that the interests Of the metrOpole state and big COpper, or big capital in general are identical. I suspect that the latter would not be unhappy if the UN were to emerge as a new state structure and instrument with the an ’5 127 gmwer to establish and enforce the rules of the game in underseas mining. This would be acceptable if the social investment necessary for private capital accumulation (mapping of the undersea deposits, research on extraction techniques) were also to take place under UN auspices but with private appropriation of the profits from mining itself. The outcome would be an international political capitalism with stability, predictability, and security greatly en— hanced for private capital. This internationalization of capitalist rationality would further emancipate the multi— nationals from their metropole states and at the same time increase the dependency Of hinterland states on the policies of these same multinationals. CHAPTER 4 THE STATE AS STRUCTURE: SOCIAL CAPITAL State Social Investment in Physical Capital: Diversification and Stockpiling State social constant capital investment in physical capital increases the productivity of a given amount of labor power and is thus indirectly productive. State out- lays Of this nature remain only indirectly productive be- ‘1' 3 v. Tut—t"? cause monopoly capital socializes much or all Of the costs Of planning and developing physical capital projects while continuing to privately appropriate the profits. Thus these _state outlays'only indirectly lessen the fiscal crisis, i.e., only through the-increased tax revenues arising from pri- vate capital accumulation. This category Of state expendi— ture has served the capital accumulation needs Of big copper in two ways. On the one hand it has furthered efforts at diversification while on the other it has evened out the rate of capital accumulation on both an inter and intra in- dustry basis. The former case involves state outlays which were originally intended to provide a stockpile of materials for national defense. An examination Of these outlays pro- vides a first picture of the state as structure, the synthe- sis of state and capital. 128 .9.- ~- 'Iv ‘In. r. "is a . '\ N'l i 129 During the last half century the rate of growth Of demand for aluminum has been much more rapid than for copper. Although bauxite was not produced until 1910, by the 1960's the expansion of capitalist world aluminum output had made it the largest nonferrous metal by tonnage produced. The divergent rates of growth for the two metals is expected to continue for the remainder of this century. Aluminum and copper are competing metals for several industrial uses,. particularly in the electrical goods industry which has pro- vided 50 percent of the market for COpper since the 1920's (Brown and Butler, 1968:69-75; Parsons, 1933:20). Thus, some of the expansion of demand for aluminum has come at the expense of copper. For example, aluminum has displaced cop- per in high voltage overhead power lines (Brown and Butler, 1968:166). Government studies in the 1950's showed that during the 1945-1954 period, the 25 industries consuming 69 percent Of copper base mill products and 38 percent of aluminum base mill products increased their demand for cop- per only 1.6 percent while their demand for aluminum rose 66.3 percent (Copper, Spring 1957:5—6). Thus, despite cop- per's established position as a monopoly sector industry, its relative standing was being eroded. Even within the monopoly sector the law of uneven deve10pment was working itself out. The decision on metal choice has in fact been cumula- tive as the law suggests: once the shift to aluminum oc- curs it is seldom reversed due to the investment in new M 130 equipment, the commitment to new size specifications, and the advantages of established and stable relations between buyers and sellers. For example, Ford's decision to pur- chase 30,000 tons of molten aluminum per year from Kaiser was considered a breakthrough for the aluminum industry (Girvan, 1971a:23). There are, of course, limits to the possible aluminum penetration of copper markets. Thus, alu- minum's greater volume per unit of conductivity means that copper's position in telephones and electric motors remains secure. Further, an era Of energy shortage gives copper a cost advantage. Producing a ton Of the red metal requires less than 20 percent Of the KW hours required to produce a ton Of aluminum. Overall, however, a major force behind the efforts of big copper to develop new markets has been the penetration of aluminum into COpper's traditional markets. Differing growth rates have not been the only contrast between copper and aluminum. While there have long been three major copper producers and numerous lesser firms, Alcoa was the sole domestic producer of aluminum until the end of World War II. During the war the state built alu— minum facilities to meet the increased wartime demand. With the end Of the war came the question of the disposal of these facilities: should the state sell them to the company with the most experience in the field, Alcoa, thus entrench- ing and appearing to legitimate a monopoly or should new producers be sought? The decision would Obviously affect both the total rate Of capital accumulation and particularly l“ 131 Um rates for individual corporations. The final decision vms designed to both encourage competitiveness in the indus- try and to increase the rate of growth of aluminum output. The state's 301 million dollar investment in bauxite mines, smelters, and alumina plants was disposed of for $101.1 mil— lion to Reynolds and Kaiser. State social constant capital expenditures tO increase aluminum production did not stop with the sales to Reynolds and Kaiser, however. During this same period the state Of- fered favorable terms for amortization Of investment and a five year market guarantee to new capital entering aluminum production (Brown and Butler, 1968:145; Girvan, l97la:82-83). Big copper had long been concerned by competition with alu- minum and in 1952 Anaconda (along with two smaller firms, Ormet and Harvey) became a reducer Of alumina. Although initially dependent on Reynolds as an alumina source, Ana- conda quickly began efforts to integrate forwards and back— wards, researching the possibility of producing alumina from clays in Georgia and Idaho and establishing an aluminum fabricating facility. In the former effort they were aided by USBM research while their venture into fabricating was facilitated by the similarity with COpper fabricating (Brown and Butler, 1968:145-147; EQMJ, November 1952:136 and Janu- ary 1957:80-85; Anaconda Annual Reports). While Anaconda has remained the fourth largest producer Of aluminum in the U.S., aluminum output has expanded much more rapidly than copper production, increasing over 200 percent in the last 132 cmcade. Together with Ormet and Harvey, Anaconda has cut into the market shares Of the big three in aluminum (Brown and Butler, 1968:27; EEMJ, various issues; Anaconda Annual Imports). The internationalization Of capital has also been a force behind Anaconda's aluminum venture. Agreements with the French firm Pechiney (the world's fifth largest aluminum producer) enabled Anaconda to acquire advanced reduction technology for their Columbia Falls, Montana plant. Frus~ trated with the efforts to produce aluminum economically from alumina clays, Anaconda has joined with Reynolds and Kaiser in the Alpart Project. The three companies will mine bauxite and reduce alumina in Jamaica, shipping the product to their U.S. plants for further processing (ggflg, January 1967:81, OECD, 1969:58). On the one hand, these state expenditures represent social investments in physical capital: the below cost sale of the plant and equipment, favorable amortization terms, and market guarantees. From the perspective of the major political economic forces behind these decisions, that is undoubtedly the correct classification. However, if analyzed from the perspective of the copper industry suffering from the costs of uneven development in its competitive struggle with aluminum, these state expenditures functioned as social expense outlays. The divergent interests of copper and alu— minum producers were integrated within the larger class imperative of an increased rate of capital accumulation. The interpenetration of state and capital converted interest 133 group conflict, which "is inconsistent with the survival and expansion Of capitalism" (O'Connor, 1974:67), into the common denominator of class interest (cf O'Connor, 1974: 65-70 on this point). Further, state expenditures made it possible for Anaconda to socialize the risks of uneven de- velopment. Fluctuations in Anaconda's rate of capital ac— cumulation were no longer tied to the fortunes of copper in its competitive struggle with aluminum. Rather, different regions, towns, or segments of the international proletariat within the organizational framework Of Anaconda now bore the brunt of the shifting demand for the two metals. Domestical- ly, Anaconda, Montana--1ong time center of Anaconda's copper processing--declines while Columbia Falls, Montana, with its new aluminum refining and fabricating capacity, grows.l In- ternationally, Anaconda's Chilean copper competed with its Jamaican aluminum. Anaconda, however, kept on growing. The unceasing efforts of capital to transform external unpredictable outcomes of the market into internal con- trollable decisions of the firm (Galbraith, 1967:Chapter 2), is characteristic of big copper also. Here the concern is with "wasteful" competition and the problems Of over and under production. The lack of control over production levels and existence Of alternating periods Of slack and capacity- straining demand means uneveness in the rate of capital ac- cumulation by price instability. The result is difficulty in corporate planning and, once again, the spector of alu- minum penetration of copper markets since the higher degree 134 of concentration in the production of aluminum has resulted in greater price stability for that metal in recent years. As a selling point, price stability is particularly impor- tant in the producer goods sector of the economy where the ability to control, and if possible, reduce, prices is em- phasized (Baran and Sweezy, 1966:68-70). This is difficult if the price of an important component of the final good, such as copper, is not readily predictable. State expenditures for stockpiling enter here since they both further the accumulation of capital and act as a price stabilization mechanism. At the same time, the network of stockpile and purchasing agencies, legislative guide- lines, and private capital graphically illustrate the state as structure. Stockpiling, of course, was not begun with these purposes in mind. Although industry publications such as EQMJ had been calling for such action as a "preparedness measure" and incidentally as an industry relief measure (EEMJ, January 1939 editorial), well before World War II, it was the war itself which provided the impetus for state stockpiles. The rationale lay in the key role that many minerals, including copper, play in armaments production. Since the major sources of several of these metals are out- side the U.S., governmental stockpiling would assure access to the needed raw materials. Thus, the initial state ex- penditures in this area should be understood as social ex- penses and only secondarily as social investment. 135 All of this seems straightforward enough, but (1) the ideology Of national interest is a very malleable one and (2) once a national security establishment is created, the agencies involved attempt to maximize their resources and functions, that is to tie themselves more firmly to expanding industrial sectors and, in turn, to aid in that expansion (see Barnet, 1973:13ff on this latter point). Let me take these complicating factors in order. The initial stockpile legislation, the 1939 Strategic Metals Act, specified only that the minerals and metals involved should come from U.S. producers but not necessarily from domestic ores. A con- flict over this question quickly deveIOped. Competitive capital argued that national security and national defense meant national--the support of existing domestic producers and, as in the case of copper, where domestic capacity was lacking, state constant capital expenditures to increase the output Of the resources in question. Thus, stockpiles were quickly tied to capital accumulation through the ide- ology of "a national minerals policy." Big copper, along with other multinational mining corporations responded that the goal was adequate resources for national defense and that whether these came from domestic ores or foreign ores under the control of U.S. producers was a secondary issue. The defense policy of these interests was often cast in terms of a "Western Hemisphere policy, arguing that we could retreat to "our" hemisphere and have all raw materials necessary for an extended war. (The information in this 136 paragraph is drawn from the following sources: Bidwell, 1958:38-42; pggg, 1939-1940; and McMahon, 1965:327-328.) The political conflict between large and small producers mirrored a differing conception of future of the capitalist political economy. Competitive capital sought to maximize the rate of capital accumulation for national and regional capital while monopoly capital saw the imperative of capital accumulation on the international level. Competitive capital found its political voice in this debate in the members of Congress from the western mining states while big capital pursued their interests through the 1» Secretaries of Navy, War, and Defense (EEMJ, 1940-1941). The simple exigencies of an escalating war demand for raw materials propelled the state towards the policy Of big capital but part of the political goals Of small capital (including competitive copper) were realized in the post war stockpile programs. That is to say that while state constant capital outlays were responsive to the demands of monopoly capital, the state also incorporated the potential- ly politically disruptive pressures of competitive capital. TO understand this process we must consider the second point raised above, the ability of state agencies to link their survival and growth to the demands of capital and the stra- tegic interests of the state. Whatever the outcome of the debate over the responsi- bility for the origins of the Cold War (contrast Schlesinger, 1967 and Williams, 1967) one reality cannot be denied: the 137 Cold War as a militarized peace served the interests Of cap- ital and the state alike. For the mineral industry, the Cold War ideology was the framework for the continuation and expansion of state stockpiling. When the Strategic Materials Act expired in 1946, it was renewed as the Strategic and Critical Materials Stockpiling Act and retained under con- gressional control (Bidwell, 1958:39-40; Wideman, 1965:289). In the early years Of the Cold War it was still possible for state agencies tO clash over military vs. economic priori- ties as the Commerce Department and the Defense Department (DOD) did in 1948. The Commerce Department questioned the wisdom Of stockpiling metals in short supply domestically while the DOD demanded assured availability of metals for the coming conflict with the U.S.S.R. With Truman's backing, the DOD's military definition of reality triumphed (EgMJ, February 1948:121). Along with business in general, mining interests in- creasingly saw the economic and strategic needs of the nation not in conflict but as a seamless whole, the unity behind leadership in foreign affairs and domestic prosper- ity. Thus, Eéfll repeatedly argued that military prepared- ness, including stockpiling, and mineral industry growth and expansion were two results of the same state policies. Typical was a May 1948 piece by Col. G. A. Lincoln entitled "Military Strategy and Minerals." Col. Lincoln saw minerals as the key to a rising standard of living domestically (the «ever-expanding economy) and success in foreign warfare. '. ‘c '~ . . H“ 138 Stockpiles would serve both purposes and also further the political-economic thrust of the United States in the Third WOrld (EEMJ, May 1948:84-88). In that same year, another ggpl article pointed out the connection between the Marshall Plan and assured continued access Of the U.S. to mineral supplies from West Europe's colonial empires (EgMJ, Septem- ber 1948:70-74). Two years later, the fate of the U.S. mineral industry was linked to the future of civilization itself in an editorial entitled "A Mining Program to Defend Civilization." Once again state social constant capital investment was to provide production incentives and finan- ‘Ei‘. cial aid to mining (EEMJ, September 1950:66-70). State response to the perceived threat took the form of the Defense Production Act of 1950 (DPA). The DPA. created a second stockpile, under the control of the execu- tive, and established the Defense Minerals Exploration Ad- ministration tO provide financial support in the exploration and development of minerals in the U.S. (Brown and Butler, 1968:1543 McMahon, 1965:325; Wideman, 1965:289). Aid took the form of tax concessions and a guaranteed market for a state—capital negotiated portion of the output of mines de— ‘veloped under the program. By the early 1960's it was be- lieved by at least one expert in the area that the DPA pro- gram (under which over 800,000 tons of COpper were pur- chased) had boosted U.S. copper output above the level the (wast/price relationships prevailing in the industry would otherwise have produced (Herfindahl, 1959:138) . c| r/ 139 Like and ideology in which the central tenet is national interest or national security, the Cold War weltangschauung proved quite flexible. In 1954, still a third, Supplemental, stockpile was established, but this time in Opposition to the priorities of mining capital. The metals in this stock- pile were to be acquired neither from U.S. domestic nor foreign-owned mines, but directly from the stocks on hand in third world nations. These were the halycon days of agri- cultural surpluses and the synthesis of state and agricul- tural interests, acting through the Department of Agricul- ture, had concluded that farmers could be aided and the ‘ - !\ ~' -._._ . national defense served by the exchange of agricultural com- modities with raw materials from allied nations with a food deficit (Bidwell, 1958:43-44). Mining capital, including big copper, Opposed this Supplemental Stockpile on three . _grounds: (l)'it was administered and controlled by state agencies tied to-agriculture rather than mining; (2) it was .thought to be a disruptive influence on the world market, although producers were split over this point; and (3) re- leases from this stockpile were beyond the control of mining interests. In June of 1957 copper and other mining inter- ests forced a temporary halt in this stockpile through a congressional investigation of the agricultural surplus/raw materials barter scheme. When the Supplemental Stockpile was reinstated later in the year, it was under much tighter administrative control and a sharp decline in the amounts involved resulted (E&MJ, June 1957:78, 118 and August 1957: 128). 140 Despite the demise of the Supplemental Stockpile, state accumulation of raw material stocks continued throughout the 1950's and into the 1960's. However, the rate of stockpile accumulation was clearly subordinated to the rate of private capital accumulation. When the demand for a mineral was particularly weak, stockpile purchases would increase and political pressure would mount for raising the stockpile ceiling. On the other hand, as demand recovered, stockpile purchases could be delayed with the firm retaining the right to sell increased amounts to the state in the future to meet its stockpile quota. While this pattern was Of greatest importance to competitive capital whose marginality is under- lined during periods Of slack demand, big copper was also involved. Thus Anaconda and Kennecott used this mechanism to hold onto their dominant position in the production of 1_ tin and zine,~metals in which the U.S. is a high coSt pro- ducer. Even within the copper industry itself, the same ‘dynamic operated. For example, in early 1957 Egg; reported a market decline in demand for copper stimulating copper sales to the state following an extended period during which the state allowed capital to divert output needed under the stockpiling program to civilian use (Egflg, January 1957:119; see Eéfli throughout the 1950-1960 decade for evi- art of the operations of private capital, in effect canal- :ize the socialized state expenditures on salaries for pro— ifessors, clerical workers, and maintenance personnel to the loenefit Of capital. Meanwhile, graduate students, many sup- Eported by state scholarships, are oriented towards a future ‘Nith big copper. What has happened is that the philanthropic sections of big copper--the grants and the locations of the .labs on or near the campuses—-have taken the (supposed) :social rationality of state legislatures and pbulic univer- sities and rechanneled it along the direction of its own lPrivate rationality, creating friends and political allies in the process. Once again it is a case of the "private appropriation Of state power for particularistic ends." 'The relationship involved is not unlike that prevailing be- tlween the suburb and the city in which the dominant partner ITedirects the structure of the political economy along IDsths which are favorable to its own growth and expansion ¥_____ .72. N 'I *1 162 (see O'Connor, 1974:125-129). In the case of big copper, the interpenetration of the state and capital through smcialized costs and private appropriation Of profits be- cmmes so total as to almost defy analytic efforts at separ- ation. Surely Marx's comment on the joint stock company, that it "represents social production within the shell Of private prOperty," is even more applicable today than in his own lifetime. State Social Consumption Social capital outlays for social consumption, that is Estate social variable capital expenditures that lower the crosts of reproducing labor power, are difficult tO link ESpecifically to the dynamics of copper. Most Of these bud- QJet categories-~urban renewal, unemployment insurance, ‘Vvorkmen's compensation-~are grounded in the universalistic JLegal criteria Of capitalism rather than the particularistic Jrequirements of any given segment of capital. This feature (of these state outlays rebounds to the benefit of capital :Since the free mobility of labor means that the reproduction <:osts Of labor power in general should be lowered rather 'than the labor power employed by a particular capital. How- eVer, copper, along with other mineral industries, is inter- tlwined with the state in specific and somewhat unique ways. Tune demand for COpper is concentrated in the most volatile EBlement of the business cycle, the producer goods industries. 'anus, the yearly fluctuations of COpper output are consid- Ei‘rlc'ably greater than those of the GNP growth rate. This % _ up. Mr '90. . .,. .u 163 dynamic plus the tendency Of monopoly sector output to grow through productivity gains rather than through labor force growth creates employment fluctuations in COpper which greatly exceed those for the total political economy. While GNP growth has been negative only once in the post World War II era (1949; in constant dollars 1954, 1958, and 1970 were all years of negative GNP growth), copper out- put has shown no such stability. Declines were registered in domestic mine prOduction in more than half of the 1944- 1973 years despite an overall increase in output. Similar- .ly, although total U.S. nonagricultural employment showed a Iaegative growth rate in only 1949, 1954, 1958, and 1961, eemployment in copper declined in these four years and in 3L952, 1956, 1957, 1962, 1964, 1967, 1969, and 1970 as well. st a result, the state is forced to make greater outlays for IJnemployment insurance per number of employees in the cop- Iper industry than in the economy as a whole. Analogously, ‘the accident rate is higher in mining than in most other (occupations, requiring greater workmen's compensation pay- Inents per hours worked to copper than in most manufacturing iand service industries. (Data for this paragraph from E997 SEQmic Report Of the President, 1973; United States, Dept. c3f Commerce, n.d.:selected issues.) CHAPTER 5 THE STATE AS STRUCTURE: SOCIAL EXPENSES The Domestic Costs Of Capital Accumulation There is nothing to be gained by finding L_ fault with any of this business-like enterprise “7 that is bent on getting something for nothing at any cost. After all, it is safe and sane business, sound and legitimate, and carried on i _ blamelessly within the rules of the game. One may also dutifully believe that there is no harm done, or at least that it might have been worse. --Thorstein Veblen, The Vested Interests and the Common Man The business of getting something for nothing, that is ‘the drive Of capital to use labor power as a means to sur- jplus value rather than as the end of social production, is (an integral feature of the accumulation of capital. Popu- lations, communities, and regions are foced to bear the social costs of the expansion of capital while the gains are appropriated privately (Gorz, 1971). This ability of Capital to externalize the diseconomies and internalize the economies of growth necessitates considerable outlays for ilegitimation, for "the collective welfare," on the part of tune state. Of course, the ever-expanding economy--the Errowth and well being of monopoly capital--is the key ele- I“ent in the state's conception Of the collective welfare. Nonetheless, these social expenses represent the state's 164 u u; . u. 165 effort to integrate the private rationality of individual capitals, the interest group consciousness Of industry as- sociations, and the functional prerequisites Of capital as a system. To carry out this task, the state requires a conception of the collective welfare which, like the con— ception of the strategic interest which informs the deci— sions on social investment, transcends the needs, and may at times clash with the interests of, any given capital. While this type of Outlay does not increase surplus value, it becomes the basis of the security--"protection from the political attacks latent in any formally democratic struc- ‘ture"--which provides the political environment within ‘which monopoly capital can function. Here I consider big copper and state social expenses lander two headings: the question Of present and future iaccess to mineral lands and the problem of air pollution. iflhile the latter-issue has generated more visible political (conflict, the former goes to the roots of the rules of the (capitalist game as practiced in the U.S. Just as capital .in general seeks to create and maintain the option of ex- ansion abroad, so the mineral industry in general and big <=Opper in particular are vitally interested in continued access to potential mineral lands for expansion at home. Turns, the political conflict over the future Of public 14inds brought out the mineral industry as a political bloc. trlle struggle around the issue of air pollution was fought along more particularistic lines. For copper, this latter Li 166 issue turned on the level of sulphur emissions allowable from copper, lead, and zinc smelters. In each case, copper, the state, and ecology groups are involved. Each brings a somewhat different conception about how the costs and bene- fits of capitalist development should be distributed. Neither issue has reached final settlement at this writing. However, state social expense outlays have already emerged as an important element in state efforts to mediate the con- flicting interests.’ The most immediately Obvious social cost of copper ruining is the destruction of the land. From an ecological Ipoint of view, an Open pit COpper mine is simply a large-- 63nd growing--hole in the ground. This is necessarily the (case for two reasons flowing from the nature of copper min- eeralization. On the one hand, copper deposits are below 1the surface-of the earth. Thus, if open pit mining is to Ice used, and this method is the cheapest and safest avail- eable, the overburden (the land above the copper deposit) Inust be stripped and discarded. Second, the ore to metal ratio in copper mining is among the highest in the mineral industries. It is usual to remove more than a hundred tons of earth to Obtain one ton of metal. In fact, copper mining r emoves more earth than virtually any other human activity (see Minerals Yearbook or Mineral Facts and Problems for statistical information on these relationships). In cases ‘VTlere the size of the deposit is large enough to insure rn<>re or less continuous usage, e.g., as at Kennecott's 7214‘- ‘- uh 167 Bingham Canyon, the problems of what to do with the exhausted mine and where to mine next do not arise. However, most cop- per deposits, including most of those owned by big copper, do come to an end and all companies are constantly involved in the search for new deposits, the struggle Of mining cap- ital to achieve control over sufficient raw materials for‘ long term planning. (See companies' annual reports for the emphasis on exploration and development.) A The drive Of mining capital to obtain assured future 'F*'J ;profits has meant intimate involvement with the politics of E jpublic lands. In the 1960's this involvement produced I several conflicts between big copper and the ecology move- ment over the use of these lands. Within the state as structure this conflict was manifested in the Department of the Interior which is responsible both for supervising min- "~- eral exploration and development and for the creation and administrationflof national parks and recreation areas. In fact, this dual responsibility is one of the reasons that mineral interests mounted the political push (discussed above) for a Department of Natural Resources during the last decade. An early conflict between big copper and groups attempting to limit the environmental impact of Inining occurred over Washington's Glacier Peak area. Kenne- cott.had located a copper deposit in the region but announced -in 1961 that operations had to be curtailed due to "uncer- ‘tainties" over the creation of a Glacier Peak Wilderness lkrea (E&MJ, June 1961:19). .As noted previously, it was also 168 during this same period that both Kennecott and Anaconda testified against the reclassification Of land near Anaconda, Montana as a wilderness area (gggg, April 1962:136) and against the creation of a national park near Wheeler Peak, Nevada where Anaconda was developing its beryllium mine for the AEC (E&MJ, July 1962:118; see company reports for the concern over the issue Of public lands). The initial response of the state to these conflicts was an attempt at rationalization of land access and use through the establishment of the Public Land Law Review Com- mission. The commission heard evidence and arguments from the several interests concerned with the use of public lands, including big COpper. Kennecott suggested that the commission include in its task the study of the use of pub- lic lands and policies for the development of these lands (E&Mg, May 1966:28). Four years later, the commission re- leased a report which was welcomed by EgMJ as a boost to the mining industry and a recognition of national priorities. The key section of the report called for mineral development to take preference over "some or all" alternative uses of public lands. Further, the state was to conduct a thorough study to determine the mineral value of these lands before a decision on their allocation was made (E&MJ, July 1970: 16). This latter concern, the need for a national inventory of mineral resources, has also been echoed by the Secretary of the Interior in his reports under the Mining and Minerals Policy Act Of 1970. 169 The release of the commission's report signaled the be- ginning of a political debate over the relationship between mining capital and the state. There is widespread feeling that the existing relationship, represented by the mining code Of 1872, needs to--and would be--a1tered (of company reports during 1971-1973). In an October 1972 speech before the New York Mining Club, a Kennecott vice president sum- marized big copper's view of the issues involved. The shift from rural to urban political dominance, the rising concern with the social costs of pollution and surface mining, and the high accident rate in mining all pointed towards new actions on the part of the state. Mining capital itself was concerned with incentives for development of the re- maining mineral resources of the nation and the problem of security of tenure. The task facing the mining industry is to outline, both for itself and the public, a consistent role for the state, particularly in the areas of regulation and foreign vs. domestic sources of mineral growth (E&MJ, December 1972:59). By December of that year, Interior was calling for industry to talk about ppg_the 1872 code should be altered (E&MJ, December 1972:21). No final action has been taken at the time of this writing. However, it is al- ready clear that the distribution of the social costs of Inining and the role Of state social expense outlays have emerged as key issues. Proposed revisions revolve around the questions of control over subsoil rights, royalties to support state policies, the costs of land reclamation, and 170 incentives to allow the generally high cost U.S. mine indus- try to expand domestic production, etc. (E&MJ, January 1972: 126, August 1972:23, and December l973:9). Smelter pollution has been the social cost of capital accumulation by big COpper which has had the greatest polit- ical visibility during the last five years. Overall, about 12 percent of the sulphur oxide omissions in the U.S. atmo- sphere is sulphur dioxide (802) given off by COpper, lead, f" and zinc smelters. While heating with coal and petroleum produces about four times as much sulphur oxide emissions, 1 COpper, lead, and zinc smelters--Often the same facility-- i 5 are a concentrated source Of such pollution (E&MJ, August 1970:95-97). This is particularly the case since these smelters are not distributed throughout the U.S. Instead, 85 percent of U.S. copper smelter capacity is located in six states: Arizona, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico, Utah, and Washington (McMahon, 1965:256). In these states the smelters are often a major source of sulphur oxide emissions: in 1970 Kennecott's Garfield smelter was identified as the single largest source Of 802 in Utah (E&MJ, July 1970:98). While the conflicts which developed around the issue of smelter pollution during 1969-1973 Often found big COpper pitted against the ecology movement and state agencies, this is too simple an interpretation of the interests involved. Monopoly capital is not opposed to environmental and con- servation measures and, in fact, class conscious members Of the capitalist class recognize the necessity of such measures. 171 Indeed, as a part of the rationalization function of polit- ical capitalism, such measures may even serve the long term interests of capital, regulating cutthroat competition that threatens to exhaust resources and absorbing political at- tacks arising from discontent over the social costs Of cap- ital accumulation. Thus, as early as 1959, Eéfll responded to Arizona's concern over smelter pollution with an article calling for industry to act on the problem (E&MJ, March 1959:120 and July 1959:65-74; in 1973 the magazine did, how- ever, quote an official of big copper to the effect that the ecology movement "got things moving" EEMJ, April 1973:50E). Monopoly capital in general and big COpper in particu- lar do, however, have two overriding interests in the ques- tion of pollution control. First, no one firm or industry can afford the expenses Of pollution control and still re- main competitive (O'Connor, l974:l76-l77). Thus, anti- pollution programs necessitate an expanded role for the state and increased state social expense outlays. In fact, if possible, the control Of pollution by industry should be- come a further means of capital accumulation, i.e., state social expense outlays should be turned into state social investment expenditures. This will only happen if the sec- ond interest of monopoly capital is realized. Any expanded state program which involves new state agencies requires a new synthesis Of state and capital. Thus, big COpper strug- gled to make the new anti-pollution bureaucracies responsive not only to the legitimation function of the state, but also 172 to the state's capital accumulation function. The monopoly Of expertise within big copper and state agencies, such as the USBM, which were part of the pre-existing synthesis of state and capital was a key factor in the outcome Of this struggle. In sum, rather than fighting anti-pollution policies as a whole, big copper focused on the qeustions of who would make policy and who would finance the implementa- tion of policy (of Weinstein, 1968 for a discussion of earlier political economic struggles involving the social costs of capital accumulation). The answer to the question "who will pay" came first. In 1968 the state released a report which pegged the cost Of treatment of mining wastes to meet proposed state stan— dards at $1.5 billion, double that for any other industry (E&MJ, March 1968:17). In 1969 monopoly capital Obtained passage Of legislation providing for tax breaks on the cost Of pollution control equipment, i.e., state social expense outlays were to socialize the costs of capital accumulation (E&MJ, July 1969:15). A year later President Nixon further encouraged the socialization of the costs of accumulation, arguing that "the price of goods should be made to include the costs of producing and disposing Of them without damage to the environment" (quoted in EgMJ, February 1970:16). Big copper's stake in the issue was recognized that same year when Kennecott president Frank Milliken was appointed to Nixon's 55 member industrial pollution control council. The council was to advise the president and the new environ- ‘n 173 mental control agencies of the state on the environmental priorities and programs of capital (E&MJ, May 1970:17). It was also in 1970 that the conflict over the control Of smelter pollution, particularly the allowable level of SO2 emissions, began in earnest. In the previous year, the Arthur G. McKee Company had submitted a report to the Na- tional Air Pollution Administration (an EPA forerunner) which recommended a cut back of 90 percent in the level of SO2 emissions from Smelters. This 90 percent recommendation was supplementary to the ambient air standards also drawn up by the state and which required implementation plans to be submitted by the individual states (E&MJ, July 1971: 61-62). In 1970 and early 1971 all six COpper states moved to shift the social cost of smelter pollution to capital by adopting, or taking steps towards the adoption of, the 90 .3 percent control of SO2 recommendation (E&MJ, August 1970: 98-99). Big copper proclaimed its willingness to meet the iambient air standards but resisted making the investment necessary for existing smelters to meet the 90 percent stan- dard (E&MJ, July 1971:63). In the ensuing political economic battle big COpper had two major disadvantages. First, they were dealing either with new state agencies such as the EPA and various POllution control commissions or with agencies such as boards of health without established links to mining capi- ta1. Thus, the synthesis of state and capital in these new regulatory agencies was as yet unstructured. Second, big .1” A 174 copper was basically arguing from the position of its own narrow profit interests against the state's conception of the collective welfare. Big copper wasnot, however, lacking in political economic counters to these disadvantages. The ideology of national security, the existing synthesis of state and mining capital, and two organizational features of copper as a monopoly sector industry were used to good advantage in big copper's efforts to shift the social costs Of pollution to state social expense outlays. The demands of national security and the need for in- ternational economic competitiveness were the major politi- cal arguments mounted by big COpper and ably seconded by the state agencies linked to COpper. The period 1969-1973 was both the crest of the ecology movement as a political .force and a time of mounting state concern over mineral shortages. -Big COpper argued that "unreasonable" environ- mental contrels,,such as the 90 percent 802 requirement, prevented the investment of capital necessary to prevent increased dependence on foreign supplies. As early as October 1970 Anaconda announced that its copper production was down due to air quality controls on custom smelters (E&MJ, August 1970:99 and October 1970:126). Further, since Copper is a world commodity, capital said that pollution Control in the U.S. would hurt the metropole's competitive Position in world markets, worsening the already negative mineral balance of payments (E&MJ, July 1971:64). The Department Of Interior and the USBM, both part of the pre- eXisting synthesis of state and capital, used their expertise 175 to impress the importance of continued profitable capital accumulation on the new anti-pollution agencies. Interior Secretary C. B. Morton and Assistant Secretaries Dole and Wakefield repeatedly expressed concern over the influence of the ecology movement, arguing that their demands would entail a decline in U.S. mineral output and increase depen- dence on other nations (see e.g., First and Second Annual Reports of the Secretaryiof the Interior under the Mining and Minerals Poligy Act of 1970; E&MJ, September 1972:13 and December l973:9). In 1971, the USBM released its own study of the costs of pollution control. The results sup- ported the estimates Of big copper against the lower esti- mates of the EPA and backed the argument of capital that existing technology could not be expected to do the jOb (E&MJ, December 1971:78). The organizational flexibility of monopoly capital was also used to make big COpper's political economic point. The internationalization of capital in the copper industry coupled with the geographical concentration of domestic smelting employment gave the companies a maneuverability denied to the individual states. Thus, big COpper threat- ened, and in a few cases actually did, cut back smelter operations in the U.S., shipping ores and concentrates abroad for smelting. The matte (smelted metal) was then imported for refining and fabricating with the claim that the additional costs of pollution control made this the cheaper method of Operation. This action demonstrated that 176 not only can international capital shift production to maxi- mize profits, it can also redistribute the social costs of capital accumulation during periods of political reform in one country or another. It thus appears that one tragic result of the demands for increased participation in mineral processing by hinterland nations may be the export of pol- lution to these nations. This will also enable international capital to prolong the life of equipment that no longer meets the pollution contrOl standards of the metropole. In the metropole itself, the threat by big COpper to export smelter Operations maximized the geographical impact of their polit- ical economic power: Arizona, with 30 percent of U.S. smelter capacity, was faced with the loss of jobs and tax revenues during a recession and the spector of foreign com- petition. This international dialectic is captured in the first response of big COpper to Arizona pressure on smelter pollution: the idea of a free zone for smelting in Mexico ' (gig, February 1967:196) . An important step in big COpper's struggle to shape anti-pollution policy was the creation of sources of ex- pertise sympathetic to the needs of big COpper for capital accumulation. Here big copper relied on already established educational and administrative ties. The Arizona Mining Association (which included Kennecott's Ray Mines Division) granted the University of Arizona $545,000 to establish an atmospheric analysis lab (E&MJ, July 1971:66). Kennecott, which owns the only Utah copper smelter, commissioned that 177 University to study the effects of S02. In 1971, Anaconda, Kennecott, Phelps Dodge, and five smaller copper producers established a research consortium on the problems of SO2 and particulate emissions by copper smelters. The consortium, called the Smelter Control Research Association (SCRA), was headed by a Kennecott vice president. Although the Justice Department expressed concern that the SCRA might violate anti-trust laws, the EPA took the side of capital and the consortium was allowed to continue (E&MJ, March 197l:9 and June l97l:7). Big COpper was thus able to pool their re- sources in the conflict over expertise and policy. The division of labor within the pollutiOn control agencies of the state graphically demonstrates the way in which the state as structure reflects the political economic power of monopoly capital. When smelter pollution first emerged as a political issue, big COpper complained of the multiplicity of state agencies and laws concerned with the ' issue (E&MJ, August 1970:101; company reports). The demand was for the creation of a centralized state regulatory agency, a function fulfilled by the newly created EPA. On the other hand, big copper could bring the most effective political pressure on the details of pollution control plans at the level of the individual COpper states. The EPA's decision to establish general guidelines but to invest re- sponsibility for implementation plans to meet these guide- lines in the states was thus ideal from the perspective of big copper. The workings of this set up can best be seen 178 through a sketch of events in Arizona and Montana during the clash over the distribution of the social costs of smel- ter Operations. When Arizona and Montana first proposed the 90 percent reduction in SO2 emissions, big copper went to court, forcing open hearings on the issue. It was then more than a year before the Arizona Board of Health presented an implementa- tion plan to the EPA. Hearings revealed that secret nego- tiations between big COpper and the Arizona Board of Health had produced an agreement to allow the state health commis- sioner to gradually reduce pollution regulations. The EPA rejected the plan (E&MJ, February 1972:10). Under mounting pressure from a variety Of interests, the Arizona board then decided to send in a plan without enforcement powers, forcing the EPA to write these with the belief that ones satisfac- tory to capital would be adOpted (E&MJ, April 1972:162). This decision had been taken in the absence of the board's chairperson, however. Finally, the Board of Health sub- mitted relaxed standards and, by the end of 1972, Kennecott and other COpper companies had gone to court supporting the board's prOposals which had been rejected by the EPA (E&MJ, October 1972:34). The case was decided in favor of Kenne- cott in 1973 although the EPA planned an appeal. Montana presented a different set of problems. Only one smelter, Anaconda's million ton giant, is located in the state. Despite open hearings, the Montana Board of Health stuck by its 90 percent SO2 prOposal. After the 179 December 1971 hearings, big copper--Anaconda, Kennecott, and Phelps Dodge-~turned to the executive arm of the federal state for political support, going directly to the White House. It is interesting to note that while the Montana regulations presented only Anaconda with a problem, big cop- per evidently felt the need for a united opposition. Per- haps the perception of a domestic domino effect was involved. Whatever the case, capital succeeded in getting representa- tion from the state: White House aide Peter M. Flanigan (a partner in the investment banking house of Dillon, Read) persuaded the Denver EPA office to send a letter to the Montana Board Of Health asking for "clarification" of their 90 percent SO2 reduction standard and requesting a new hear- ing (E&MJ, March 1972 and April 1972:42). Despitethese efforts, Anaconda had to go to court against Montana and _ the EPA in a case also decided in favor of capital in 1973. Although the conflict over the distribution of the social costs of smelter pollution had not been fully re- solved by the end of 1973, the climate had certainly changed from two years earlier. State social expense outlays were integral to the shift. The USBM, which had spent several million dollars on smelter pollution research, announced the development of a pollution free process for COpper smelting (E&MJ, May 1973:32). The SCRA had been given state sanction—-and state social expense funds--through a USBM contract to study the economic feasibility Of a SO control 2 method for existing smelters (E&MJ, December l973:9). By 180 March of 1973 the EPA was putting distance between itself and the 90 percent standard: in an interview with EQMJ, a senior EPA administrator claimed that some "very junior" people were responsible for it originally (E&MJ, April 1973 50E-F). In September, the EPA recognized the need of con- tinued profitable capital accumulation by big copper, ac- cepting the SCRA's proposed closed loop control process as an interim method (E&MJ, October 1973:13). Tow years ear- lier, Anaconda had already begun the conversion of the social costs of development into further capital accumula- tion by announcing that its Chase Brass subsidiary was ex- panding into water pollution control (E&MJ, July 1971:70). A new synthesis of state and capital was emerging around the volume and distribution of state expense outlays for the social costs of capital accumulation in COpper. The Management of External Relations The dominant fact which emerges from all dis- cussions of the raw material position of the United States is the nation's increasing dependence on foreign sources of supply. --Percy W. Bidwell, Raw Materials: A Study of American Poligy Anaconda is all over the map expanding its copper output. --Anaconda advertisement in the mid-1960's showing map Of Western Hemisphere indicating Anaconda facilities 181 Anaconda makes it in America. --Anaconda advertisement in 1971, post national- ization, showing map of U.S. indicating Anaconda facilities The social relations of capital as a system are inter- national is scope. However, from the perspective Of any given capital, the world remains a patchwork of differing legal and political systems. These differing state frame- works represent both Obstacles and Opportunities in capital's thurst for surplus value. Thus, while expanding capital may penetrate the jurisdiction Of other nation states, reliance upon its own state for military protection, diplomatic rep- resentation, and economic aid remains fundamental. Metro- pOle based capital in particular tends to see the function of the state in the management of external relations as the creation of—a "political and financial climate both here and abroad...conducive to overseas investment" (Augustus C. .Long, Chmn. Texaco, June 1957, quoted in Engler, 1961:190). On the one hand, then, there is a "blending Of public and private" (Engler, 1961), a synthesis of state and capital abroad, arising from the perception of mutual needs, a shared conceptual framework of free enterprise and private property, and a two way flow of personnel (Engler, 1961: 247-247; Miliband, 1969:83-87; Murray, 1971:96-99; Tanzer, 1970:55). Nowhere is this identity of the state and its own capital closer than when it is a question of the sur- vival of the latter. Both capital and the kapitalistate 182 find nationalization (the expropriation of the expropriators) repugnant, particularly if "prompt, adequate, and just" (the phrase of former Secretary of State John Foster Dulles) com- pensation is not forthcoming. On the other hand, the state is not simply the servant of capital in the expansionary dynamic of the latter. As I argued in the theoretical discussion of the state and the changing nature of liberal doctrine, and as I tried to dem- onstrate in the empirical discussion of stockpiling, the state has its own strategic interests. In turn, these are part of a larger conception of national interest. Thus, state action in regards to a particular corporation, com- modity, or hinterland may conflict with the narrow profit needs of any given capital (Girvan, 197laz36-37; Warren, 1971). The size of the capital in question, its role in the total foreign investment stake of national capital, and the impact offla given capital on the national balance of payments are all part of the parameters within which the state acts (Tanzer, 1970:52-54). Further, we must also consider the relative power of the states involved: metro- pole and hinterland states are not equal participants in the system of world capitalism. Finally, while metropole capital may dominate a hinterland state, this is not the case with a metropole state. Here the very process of the internationalization of capital may strengthen the state and the resources which the latter can bring to bear in the pursuit Of its, admittedly imperfect, perception of the interests of the system as a whole (Warren, 1971:86-87). 183 The attempt to realize both its particular definition of the national interest and the demands of expanding capi- tal require large, and growing, state outlays which may be classified as social expenses. That is to say that these outlays are neither directly nor indirectly productive. Once again, unproductive must not be confused with unneces- sary: without the maintenance of the Option of expansion, it is unlikely that the system of capital could survive (Magdoff, 1969:14, 20-21; Williams, 1964:Chapter 2). The root cause of these social expense outlays is the inter- national uneven development and social disruption which have been part and parcel of the expansionary dynamic of capital. Of course, as outlines in Part II, uneven deve10p- ment also manifests itself on the national level.. However, the vertical integration of monopoly capital across national boundaries means that the backwash effects of expansion are concentrated in the hinterlands of world capitalism while the spread effects are canalized to the benefit of capital in particular and the metropole regions as a whole in gen- eral (Meeropol, 1972:78-80; Myrdal, 1971:26-33; see Beck- ford, 1972 for a brilliant analysis of this process). Thus uneven development is more marked on the international level (as the UN puts it, the gap between the rich and poor nations increases) than on the national level. The outcome of this cumulative inequality has been growing efforts by hinterland states to alter this dynamic. I-I' r'I 184 The efforts of hinterland states to counter the inter- national dynamics of uneven development have repeatedly con- flicted with the interests of metropole capital and/or state. For big copper, it has been the efforts of the Chilean state to obtain a greater "take" from the copper mining and pro- cessing investments of Anaconda and Kennecott which has been the focus of the external relations function of the U.S. state during the last three decades. In the 1950's the struggle turned on the issues Of prices and markets; in the 1960's the question of control was posed in terms of parti- cipation through "Chileanization"; and, as the 1970's began, the stakes were raised to nationalization. None of these conflicts have occurred solely between the Chilean state and U.S. capital. At each juncture the U.S. state has been involved, acting on a particular definition of strategic _ and national interests and using social expense outlays in an attempt to resolve the conflicts. During the Second World War the U.S. state froze the price of copper at 12¢ per pound and allocated U.S. output entirely to war needs. Both the freeze and the allocation applied not only to domestically mined COpper but to for- eign produced COpper under the control of U.S. capital as well. When copper prices were decontrolled at the end of the war, the price per pound quickly rose to over 20¢. Thus Chile paid--one estimate friendly to the U.S. suggests $120 to $500 million--for the U.S. war effort (Reynolds, 1965: 240). Shortly after the Korean War began, the U.S. state 185 again attempted to freeze COpper prices, this time at 24.5¢/ lb. However, several political groups in Chile had profited from the WWII experience and pressured the Chilean state to demand higher prices. Unlike WWII, the London Metals Ex- change (LME) continued to function and shipping lanes to West European and Japanese markets remained open. Thus, the Chilean state had increased room for maneuver. The first response of the U.S. state to Chilean demands for greater returns was the May 1951 Washington Conference. The state agreed on a 3¢/lb. premium for Chilean copper entering the U.S. Big copper was close to the negotiations and Kennecott, through its Chilean subsidiary Braden COpper Company, agreed to loan Chile the money to modernize the port of San Antonio, the chief shipping and receiving center for Braden(§§MgL June 1951:138; Gedicks, 1973:6-7). In return, the Chilean _ state agreed to restrict copper exports to the capitalist world and to eut-its growing exports of semi-manufactures. 'A maximum of 20 percent of the output of U.S. owned mines would go for domestic Chilean consumption and semi-manufac- tured exports under the control of the state (E&MJ, February 1952:79-81; Girvan, 1972:19). Even at the time of the Washington Conference Chile was able to sell the state marketed 20 percent at a price double the 27.5¢/lb. the U.S. was paying. This wide and growing world/U.S. gap continued to exert pressure on the Chilean state to realize greater returns from COpper and in May of 1952 Chile repudiated the Washington Conference price A :qul . . u R .‘.a. '1'? fi-’ NIA- ..‘hvh 1‘. .g. . .. D‘- ~‘H '- 9 g LA]! ’I a n (I) Q , u 186 agreements. After meetings with representatives of the U.S. state, the Chilean state pegged COpper prices to the LME, took over the marketing of copper, and authorized the executive to determine the proportion of exports in refined form. The Chilean Central Bank purchased the copper from the companies at the official U.S. price and sold it on the world market, the difference accruing to the Chilean state (E&MJ, June 1952:104; NACLA, 1972:113-114). The U.S. state allocated the higher priced Chilean copper entering the U.S. to all fabricators on a percentage basis, including those who were part of integrated producers and thus able to supply their needs with lower priced copper. The entry of the Chilean state into the marketing of copper in the capitalist world was a threat to the strategic interests of the U.S. state and to the efforts of the com- panies to subsume the vagaries of the market. State and capital responded by undercutting the Chilean market venture in several ways: (1) production in Chile was cut back by 15 percent; (2) investment plans in U.S. mine expansion Vwere accelerated; (3) disinvestment occurred in the com- panies' Chilean properties; (4) state stockpiles were used as market leverage; and (5) the U.S. state manipulated the international control structure for non-ferrous metals (Baklanoff, 1966:33; Girvan, 1972:19-20; NACLA, 1972:113- 114; Reynolds, 1965:247). Despite these efforts, the re- sults of the first year of the Chilean state market monopoly were spectacular—-a gain of $100 million for Chile, consider- ably in excess of the companies' payment of direct taxes 187 (Girvan, 1972:20). However, as the Korean War came to an end and capitalist world copper demand slackened, the com- bined efforts of metrOpole state and capital began to be felt and problems mounted for Chile. First, the hinterland state had little knowledge of the ins and outs Of the copper market, knowledge which Anaconda and Kennecott, like all international capital, had always considered the preserve of private capital. Second, most of Chile's potential customers were already integrated through formal and informal ties with major suppliers. Third, to lessen the squeeze between the frozen U.S. price and the higher cost of Chilean COpper entering the metrOpole at the world price, the 0.8. state released some stockpiled copper. In addition, the accumulating Chilean stocks were rejected as a possible source of stockpile copper. Fourth, working through the International Materials Conference, the U.S. state got purchases of Chilean COpper by the United Nations allies deducted from their quotas at the lower ceil- ing price (E&MJ, February 1953:78 and December 1953:169; Gedicks, 1973:7-8; Girvan, 1972:24). As long as Chile honored the 1951 agreement not to sell outside the capitalist world, the hinterland state was caught in a bind. In 1953 sales declined drastically, ex- ports falling to a level below any year since the 1930's. As copper stocks accumulated, the Chilean senate announced (1) that COpper should not be sold at less than 30¢/1b.; (2) if the metal was not of sufficient strategic significance 188 for the U.S. state to purchase it for stockpiling, it was not of enough strategic importance for sales to be limited to the capitalist world; and (3) the senate would be willing to consider any legislation designed to stimulate investment and increase output. The combined threat of sales to the U.S.S.R. and the virtual promise Of new tax and incentive policies more to the liking of capital brought the U.S. state back into negotiations (Gedicks, l973:9; Girvan, 1972: 24-25). In March of 1954 agreement was reached on the pur- chase of 100,000 tons by the U.S. state at the Chilean Price for stockpiling. Within a year, the "New Deal for COpper"--lower taxes, more favorable exchange rates, tax deductions for processing investments--was enacted by the Chilean senate (E&MJ, May 1954:107; Mikesall, l97la:372, Re)lnolds, 1965:249-250). State expenditures for legitima- “‘-.tj&>n in the—management of external relations had reinte- grErted a dependent political economy on terms satisfactory tC) the capital accumulation interests of big capital and tlua national interests of the metropole state. The Chilean political groups who had supported the New D6531 for COpper had done so in the belief that the result We‘uld be greater investment, output, and processing in (“311e, and an increased take for the Chilean state. Al- though one new mine was brought on stream-~El Salvador had already been planned as a replacement for the exhausted POtretillos, however--the rise in investment after 1955 was Shortlived (Baklanoff, 1966:335; Mamalakis, 1971:413). The 189 proportion of exports refined in Chile actually declined between 1955 and 1964, government revenues from copper fell since the increased output was not sufficient to compensate for the lowered tax rates, and Chile's share of capitalist world copper production continued its post WWII downward trend (Mikesall, l97la:373; NACLA, 1972:114; Reynolds, 1965: 253-254). Finally, the New Deal "failed to make a major dent in the outflow of foreign earned income from Chile" Mamalakis, 1971:413). Chilean unhappiness with the results of the New Deal ran so deep that when big COpper proposed new investments in 1960 in return for tax concessions and a twenty year guarantee of the continuation of the New Deal policies, the Chilean legislature rejected the proposal and passed a surtax instead (Baklanoff, 1966:337-338; Mikesall, l97la:374). By the 1964 presidential elections, copper was -, again the major issue. The pivot of the Chilean political debate over copper had shifted in the intervening years, however. Now the issues were no longer prices and markets but participation and control. The left prOposed nationalization and the Center participation through Chileanization--state "purchase of 25 percent or more of the stock in established companies» and 49 percent equity in new companies" (Edwards, T., 1972: 71- Metropole state social expense outlays in support of the centrist candidate Eduardo Frei began well before the election: when it comes to the sanctity of private property "Btropole capital and its state have a common set of \‘au dial Il.‘ \u 1 h-Oui ‘Vpg- ‘u "ov‘n . u.. 5‘. _ o.,_ ‘H 'O; ‘9 vk 190 assumptions. In May of 1964, four months prior to the election, discussions between big COpper and Frei's repre- sentatives began in New York. During the same period, Frei's prospective cabinet met with policy makers of the U.S. state in Washington (E&MJ, November 1964:23; Mikesall, l97la:375). The USIA cooperated with big COpper in an "educational cam- paign" contrasting Frei and Allende which U.S. Officials later credited with an important role in Frei's victory. The metropole state was also able to mobilize the support of private "non-political" groups such as CARE in the strug- gle to elect Frei: CARE packages were distributed in the neighborhoods of the urban poor as the election approached with suitable reminders of the connection to the good will of the U.S. and the election of Frei. Overall, a former U.S. Official estimated that it cost the metropole state $20 million to defeat Allenda (CALA; Wolpin, 1969). On a per capita basis-this social expense outlay compares quite favorably with the cost of U.S. presidential elections. While the Chileanization agreements themselves involved big copper and the Chilean state, the U.S. state was never far from the scene. Kennecott offered, and Chile accepted, a 51 percent interest in Braden, the subsidiary which owns El Teniente, and the two also worked out an expansion pro- gram to be completed in 1970. The program, which was to raise El Teniente's output from 180,000 tons per year to 280,000 tons per year, would cost $230 million, financed as follows: $27.5 million from the Chilean state's COpper 191 corporation (CODELCO), a $92.7 million loan from Kennecott, and the remaining $110.0 million from the U.S. through its Export-Import Bank (Edwards, T., 1972:17-19; Girvan, 1972: 30: Mikesall, l97la:376). In fact, Kennecott had taken the socialization of costs to a fine art. After receiving $81.6 million from the Chilean state for a 51 percent share in a mine whose total book value had been listed at $65.7 million, Kennecott turned around and loaned this sum as the bulk of its $92.7 million contribution to the mine expansion--at 5.95 percent interest! Tax rates on Kennecott's remaining 49 percent interest in Braden were reduced to the level that returns to Kennecott exceeded those prior to Chileani- zation (NACLA, 1972:115; Gedicks, 1973:13; Girvan, 1972: 57-58). As a New York security analyst for the company ex- plained it: "The beauty of the deal is that the Chileans are happy, and Kennecott is getting a bigger share of a bigger pie without any big outlay of new money from the states" (Business Week, December 7, 1969). Except, of course, the social expense outlays of the metrOpole state itself to finance the mine expansion and those which could be predicted as the nature of the deal dawned on the Chileans over the succeeding years. Under the Chileanization agreements Anaconda did not sell any of its existing property but did agree to a joint venture in a new company and an expansion of output at Chuquicamata and El Salvador. Once again the U.S. state footed part of the bill with a $58.7 million loan from the 192 Export-Import Bank for mine expansion (Edwards, T., 1972: 17-19; Mikesall, l97la:376-378). In both of the Chileaniza- tion agreements capital had managed to tie the interests of the U.S. state to the stability of the Chilean government and its continued willingness to meet its external financial obligations. State outlays were also involved in the con- flict over copper prices which developed during the Frei administration. In 1965, when the U.S. state was attempting to control the price of copper, the Chilean state saw the widening U.S./LME price gap as an Opportunity to gain in- creased revenues. In October of that year Chile raised the price of its copper to 38¢/1b. but when U.S. producers fol- lowed, the metropole state announced the release of 200,000 tons from the stockpile and forced a price rollback in the U.S. The U.S. state then negotiated a 100,000 ton purchase for defense purposes from Chile at the 36¢/lb. price. In return, Chile was granted a $10 million, 40 year low interest loan through AID to meet the rising cost of mine eXpansion. By the end of 1966 Chile had shifted to LME prices and the state began allowing Anaconda's Chilean production to enter the U.S. at these prices and allocated it to fabricators on a percentage basis, regardless of the ability of integrated capital to supply its own needs (E&MJ, February 1966:25 and January 1967:21; Mikesall, 1971a:382-383). In each of these cases, state social expense outlays were required to reinte- grate the triangle of metropole state, hinterland state, and capital. 193 The hopes for Chileanization were only partially re- alized. Although refined exports increased as a percentage of total COpper exports, total output of the Gran Mineria-- the large mines of U.S. capital--was less in 1970 than in 1963. The rhetoric and partial reality of land reform under Frei radicalized large segments of the rural population (Petras and LaPorte, l973:Chapter 5). Opposition politicians increasingly called into question the cost/benefit ratio of the Chileanization program. Finally, the intervention of Alliance for Progress programs and priorities in Chilean politics alienated much of the traditional support for the U.S. copper companies (Moran, 1972). Despite Frei's be- lated 1969 "impacted nationalization," copper was again an issue in the 1970 election. The Unidad Popular's Allende, who advocated immediate nationalization, received a plural- ity of the vote and was confirmed as president by the leg- islature. In 1971, the Chilean senate voted unanimously for Allende's nationalization prOposal. After deductions for excess profits, depreciation, and failure to maintain facilities, the Comptroller General announced that not only did Chile not owe compensation to big COpper, in fact big copper was in debt to Chile. There was a time when such an action would have stimu- lated an almost automatic response from the U.S. state: the marines. However, the 1970's are not the 1920's or even the 1950's. There are at least three factors which imposed im- portant restraints on action by the metropole state in 194 pursuit of national interest. First, Latin American nation- alism precluded any significant hemispheric support for an- other Playa Giron. Second, Indochina was still an albatross around the neck of U.S. foreign policy. State strategic and national interests in one part of the world blocked immedi- ate and decisive action in another. Finally, related to the second point, the disaster of Indochina had discredited imperial adventures among the underlying metrOpole popula- tion. Instead, the metropole state relied on the political forces set in motion by the social expenses of legitimation to undermine the Unidad Popular government abroad while social expenses at home partially compensated capital for its loss. Military aid is a major component in the total sOcial expenses involved in the management of external relations (O'Connor, 1974:151-158). Among Latin American nations Chile had received the highest per capita level of this aid from the U.S. state since WWII, a sum amounting to 10 per- cent of the Chilean defense budget. These funds were con- centrated in the areas of force modernization and weapons acquisition, the dynamic sectors of any military establish- ment, thus committing future resources to the directions marked out by the giver of aid. Nor were technology, re- placement parts, and organizational conceptions the only links between the U.S. state and the Chilean military. More than 4,000 officers of the Chilean armed forces, in- cluding future coup leader Gen. Pinochet, had been trained 195 by the U.S. military and joint naval Operations were con- ducted each year. Although all other forms of state outlays for Chile were ended with the leection of Allenda, military aid continued at double the 1967-1970 rate. These increased social expenses incurred by the state included the low cost sale of sophisticated aircraft, a move which required the waiver of congressional restrictions on arms sales to hin- terland nations (Burns, 1973:424-425; Klare, 1972:280-281, 292-302; NACLA, 1973:8-9, 12). The Chilean military, bol- stered by metropole state social expenses, emerged as the major actor in the counterrevolution which began in September of 1973. Other agencies of the U.S. state carried on the counter- revolutionary struggle in their own way. As the $2 billion in loans that Frei had negotiated came due, representatives _ Of the U.S.-state at the Parid debt renegotiations pushed a hard line. State Department spokesperson Charles Bray said that compensation to big COpper was the key issue (E&MJ, August 1972:15). Loans from the IMF and the IBRD were cut off under U.S. pressure with one exception: a World Bank loan to the Catholic University TV station which opposed Allende. The espionage arm of the state supported at least ten CIA operatives in the Santiago embassy at one time or another during Allende's tenure in office. The embassy it- self was placed under the direction of Nathaniel Davis, an ambassador with long time Central Intelligence Agency con- nections. Finally, an inflow of U.S. dollars the week before 196 the coup was indicated by the sharp fall of the dollar on the black market while interviews with striking truckers re- vealed claims Of external financial support. As in the case of the military, the social expenses necessary for the management of external relations were directed towards the strengthening of the hinterland counterrevolutionary forces (Burns, 1973:424-425; NACLA, 1972:179-208). The total social expense outlays of the metropole state in the struggle to reverse the nationalization of big copper in Chile do not stop here, however. The upsurge of hinter- land nationalism during the last two decades has resulted in a metrOpole state financed program of insurance for foreign investments (Multinational Copporations and United States Foreign Policy, 1974). Operated originally by AID and now by the Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC), the policies cover war, revolution, natural disaster, and our- rency inconvertibility. Chile, with less than 1.5 percent of U.S. capital's direct private foreign investment, ac- counted for 19.8 percent of OPIC's coverage at the end of 1968 (Multinational Corporations and United States Foreign Policy, 1974:448). Both Anaconda and Kennecott had pur- chased policies from OPIC and both companies cashed the policies after nationalization and the rejection of their protests in Chilean courts: capital turned state expendi- tures for social expenses into social investment for capi- tal accumulation. OPIC paid Anaconda's $11.89 million claim on the new La Exotica mine and $66.9 million on the 197 $92.7 million loan Kennecott had made to Chile for expansion at El Teniente. (Chilean repayments had already reduced the debt to $74.7 million.) However, OPIC refused to grant Anaconda's $154 million claim on Chuquicamata and El Salva- dor. Anaconda had saved $4 million on insurance by carrying only standby coverage on these properties at the time of Frei's 1969 impacted nationalization and OPIC had refused requests to transfer to full coverage after that date on the grounds that nationalization had already occurred. After all, $154 million on top of $78.79 million of social ex- penses would be a significant contribution to the fiscal crisis of the state (pggg, December 1971:76; November 1972: 262; and February 1973:123). The immediate outcome of the Unidad POpular'sprOject of socialist transformation in Chile has been the counter- revolution of September 1973. Social expense outlays of the metropole state were critical in the success of that struggle against the course of history. Both the counter- revolution and the state social expenses involved are also part of a larger project whose outlines were articulated by "Copper Man of the Year," Kennecott's president Frank Milli- ken, at a speech before the Copper Club in March 1973. The time has come when we must take some initiative to create business conditions. With the help of host governments in underdevelOped areas...the support of our government..and with the coopera- tion and expertise of international organizations such as the World Bank and the International Arbitration Commission, we need to createge new order and stability_for foreign investment" 198 (Quoted in EEMJ, April 1973:169, emphasis added). This new order" is, in fact, the continuation of an Old status quo, the structure of capitalist metrOpole and hinterland in the modern world, the political economy of dependency. I have looked at the metrOpole side of that relationship in the last several chapters. I now turn to a consideration of the changing forms which the Chilean hinterland has undergone in the twentieth century. I think that it's not asking too much to have our little region over here which has never bothered anybody. --Sec. of War Henry L. Stimson to Asst. Sec. Of War John J. McCloy, 1945 The produce of the earth-~all that is derived from its surface by the united application of labor, machinery, and capital is divided among three classes of the community, namely the pro- prietor of the land, the owner of the stock of capital necessary for its cultivation, and the laborers by whose industry it is cultivated. But in different stages of society, the pro- portions of the whole produce of the earth which will be allotted to each of these classes, under' the names of rent, profit, and wages, will be es- sentially different...To determine the laws which regulate this distribution is the principal prob- lem in Political Economy. --David Ricardo, The - Principles of Political Economy and Taxation 199 CHAPTER 6 THE ROOTS OF CHILEAN DEPENDENCY I The colonial heritage of Spanish America produced the time of troubles which followed the wars of independence of 1810-1822. Competitive with each other in their exports, regionally fragmented as a result of Spanish political con- trol, and ruled by classes whose orientation remained largely West EurOpean, the new nations found stability and national integration, much less Latin unity, to be elusive (Furtado, l970:2). Chile, almost alone, was an exception; and by 1830, under the leadership of Diego Portales, the country had achieved a considerable degree of political and economic stability (Pike, l963:1). This achievement was not, however, based on a social structure likely to evolve into an industrial society in the twentieth century, but rather was founded on what Claudio Veliz has called the three legged table of Chilean society: In the period between independence from Spain and the depression of 1929, the Chilean economy was dominated by three legs of the national eco- nomic table. In the first place, there were the mining exporters of the north of the country; then there were the agricultural and livestock export- ers of the south; and finally there were the large import firms which were usually located in the center, in Santiago and Valparaiso, but which op- erated in the whole country. These three pressure 200 201 groups were in entire agreement about what eco- nomic policy the country should follow. There was no other group which was able to challenge their economic, political and social power, and the three totally dominated national life, from the municipal councils to diplomatic representa- tion, economic legislation and the horse races... The mining exporters of the north of the country were free traders. This policy was not fundamentally due to reasons of doctrine--though they also had these--but rather to the simple reason that these gentlemen were blessed with common sense. They exported COpper, silver, nitrates, and other minerals of lesser importance to Europe and the United States, where they were paid in pounds sterling or dollars. With this money they bought equipment, machinery, manufac- tures, or high quality consumer goods at very low prices. It is hard to conceive of an altruism or a far-sighted or a prophetic vision which would lead these exporters to pay export and import duties with a view to the possible industrializa- tion of the country. Tied to the liberal ideas of the era, they would have argued that if it were really worthwhile developing Chilean industry, this should at least be efficient enough to com- pete with EurOpean industry which had to pay high freight charges before getting to our shores... The agricultural and livestock exporters of the South were also emphatically free traders. They sent their wheat and flour to Europe, Cal- ifornia, and Australia. They clothed their cow- boys with ponchos of English Flannel, rode in saddles made by the best harnessmakers of London, drank authentic champagne and lighted their man- sions with Florentine lamps. At night they slept in beds made by excellent English cabinet makers, between sheets of Irish linen and covered by blankets of English wool. Their silk shirts came from Italy and their wives jewels from London, Paris and Rome. For these hacendados, who were paid in pounds sterling, the idea of taxing the exPort of wheat or of imposing protective duties on imports was simply insanity. If Chile wanted its own industry to produce ponchos, very well, let it--as long as it could produce cloth of as good a quality and low a price as the English. Otherwise, the proposal was a swindle. For these simple and undoubtedly solid reasons, the mining exporter of the North and the agricultural ex- porter of the South both put pressure on the gov- ernment to keep an economic policy of free trade. 202 The big import houses of Valparaiso and Santiago also were free traders. Could anyone imagine an import firm supporting the establish- ment of high import duties to protect national industry! (Quoted in Frank, 1969:89-90). Three legged tables are notoriously unsteady and, even- tually, this proved the case for the Chilean one also. De- spite some early wobbles, it remained upright for over a century, however, and its construction dictated certain limitations and determined certain options for Chilean de- velopment. This was particularly true in regard to the mining export sector. Thus, it is worth examining the legs in some detail. Of the three legs, the fate of one was ob- viously dependent on the other two: import firms do not Operate on a large scale unless the class structure of a nation organizes the productive factors towards foreign ex- change earning exports. No export sales means low effective demand for imports. While the export of agricultural goods, particularly wheat, retained regional significance for cen- tral Chile, these exports declined relative to mineral ex- ports. It was the latter which provided most of the basis for Chilean prosperity and growth in the nineteenth century (Pendle, 1960:144-149). In this respect, the years after independence differed little from the colonial period when the desert North and Araucanian resistance in the South fed the Spanish "disease of the heart for which gold [was] the specific remedy." While gold mining in colonial Chile never reached the level of San Luis Potosi or the placer mines of New Granada, gold 203 was Chile's leading export by value. Almost half of total Chilean gold production of 1545-1958 occurred prior to in- dependence and, at its 1801-1820 peak, Chile produced 17.5 percent of the world's gold (Pederson, l966:6,166). In ad- dition, the Indians of pre-Conquest Chile had mined and worked copper as well as gold, and the Spanish continued to extract COpper from the same mines. Most Chilean copper, beginning as early as 1715, was exported to the Viceroyalty of Peru, and COpper mining remained important in Coquimbo province through the latter part of the 1700's (Pederson, 1966:6). After independence, the mineral rich Chilean earth yielded silver, a mineral little worked in the colonial era. The first big strike was at Chanarcillo in 1832 and this mine remained the most productive one throughout the nine- teenth century. Between 1832 and the last important find at Caracoles in-1870, numerous smaller deposits were dis- covered. Silver production multiplied six times between 1840 and 1855 (Frank, 1969:60-61) and Chile was third in world production at the 1887 peak (Pederson, l966:8). The decline was rapid, however, and silver was not the major vein in the third leg of the Chilean table. That role was held by COpper until the last two decades of the century. Under Spanish rule, Chilean COpper output reached 46 metric tons per year in the 1600's and jumped to 622 metric tons per year in the eighteenth century (United States, Dept. of Commerce, l960:8). As Table 5 indicates, however, it was 204 Table 5. Chilean Copper Production in the Nineteenth Century Annual Average Output in Metric Tons Chilean Production as Period (Cppper Content) % of World Production 1801-1810 1,489 9% 1811-1820 1,542 9% 1821—1830 2,735 11% 1831-1840 4,638 14% 1841-1850 8,973 20% 1851-1860 22,082 32% 1861-1870 45,974 44% 1871-1880 46,595 36% 1881-1890 36,198 16% 1891-1900 22,633 6% Source: Calculated from Skelton (1937:392). not until the middle of the nineteenth century that Chile emerged as an important producer of COpper on a world scale. The discovery of the Tamaya mines in 1833 began the rapid rise. By 1851, Chile was the leading copper producing country, replacing the United Kingdom. Chile retained this position until 1883 when the United States moved into first place (United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:87; NACLA, 1972:94; Wideman, 1965:263). As if to mirror the present and foreshadow the future configurations of world power, the old metrOpole, England, the underdeveloping hinterland, Chile, and the future metro- pole, the United States, were already linked through the commodity copper. Swansea in Wales was the world center for refining and technological innovation in copper through- out most of the 1800's. Much of the copper mined in the United States and Chile was exported to Swansea, smelted 205 and/or refined, and re-exported. Thus, the social relations of copper appeared as market relations in an international division of labor, a division which concentrated the latter stages of processing, the labor requiring technical skills and administrative abilities, and the accumulation of surplus in a capitalist metropole. While the emergence of a domestic market, the availability of financing, and the wealth of its COpper deposits enabled the United States to break out of. this pattern of the international division of labor, Chile merely exchanged one metropole for another (Pederson, 1966: 200-201; Richter, l927a:159-16l). In Chile, as elsewhere, the expanding production of copper during the nineteenth century was based on discovery of new mines with very high copper content in the ores.. At the beginning of the nineteenth century, the copper content of Chilean ore probably ran as high as 50 percent, i.e., two tons of ore yielded one ton of metal; the industry was labor intensive, and remained so despite a continuous de- cline in ore content over the course of the century to a level of 10-25 percent. While the large mines worked sul- fide ores with methods equivalent to those found in Europe and the United States, steam power, blasting powder, and pneumatic drills found limited application. Furthermore, the proliferation of small claims made consolidation for the mining of low grade ores difficult (Pederson, 1966: 191-199). Nevertheless, the industry was developed through the processing level of smelting, and controlled by Chileans. 206 In 1876, the peak year of Chilean COpper production in the nineteenth century, 90 percent of the COpper output was from Chilean owned mines (NACLA, 1972:95; Reynolds, 1965: 221). By the end of the 1890's, however, the declining cop- per content Of Chilean ores had relegated Chile to the posi- tion of a marginal producer at the same time that the new uses of copper, as a conductor of electricity and in the manufacture of automobiles, were radically increasing metro- politan demand for the metal (Reynolds, 1965:211-212). Yet the three legged table did not collapse, for Chile was blessed with still another mineral--nitrate. In fact, it can be argued that the very abundance of minerals in Chile probably made it easier to ignore the decline of COp- per and the exhaustion of the silver mines. Chilean and Peruvian capital had developed the nitrate deposits after the 1830's when the value of nitrate as a fertilizer became widely known. As the figures in Table 6 indicate, nitrate production increased rapidly thereafter. While there is a scarcity of information on the percentage of world nitrate production supplied by Chile, the prOportion must have been extremely high since Chilean nitrate was a truly unique re- source. These deposits are the only naturally occurring ones of any great size and the Haber process for mass pro- duction of synthetic nitrates was not developed until World War I (Levin, 1960:108-110). Even as late as the early twentieth century, Chile accounted for more than two-thirds of world nitrate production. 207 Table 6. Chilean Nitrate Production, Selected Years and Share of Nitrate Taxation in Government Revenue % Contribution of Nitrate Industry to Production Ordinary Revenues Year (000 Metric Tons) Year of Chile 1840* 40 1850* 30 1869* . 100 1880 223 1880 5% 1885 28% 1890 670 1890 48% 1895 56% 1900 1,643 1900 49% *Pre—1880 nitrate production not Chilean. Source: United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:98; Reynolds, 1965:33. The benefits accruing to Chile from its nitrate wealth were somewhat less than might be expected, however. Most ' of the nitrate lands, which lie in the present-day provinces of Tarapaca and Antofagasta, originally belonged to Peru and Bolivia, a division reaffirmed by an 1866 treaty with the latter nation. In the War of the Pacific (1879-1883) Chile defeated these two nations and acquired the nitrate deposits in the peace settlement. During the war, however, the bonds of the Chilean and Peruvian companies who owned the nitrate concessions were purchased at depressed prices by British investors. After the war, Chile operated the deposits through a state company for eight months but then returned the mines to private control, honoring the British 208 bondholders' claims. As a result, a substantial portion of potential nitrate revenues left the country and the nitrate deposits were integrated into the Chilean political economy only through wage payments to Chileans and via government taxation. The latter linkage was by far the most signifi- cant and its contribution to government revenues is summa- rized in Table 6. 0f perhaps greatest importance, this structure of incomplete integration of a mineral sector largely under foreign control established a pattern which was to be repeated in the twentieth century in the case of COpper (Frank, 1969:73-85; Pike, 1963:4-5). Even at the level of day-to-day life the parallels are striking. In the nitrate towns as in the copper mining camps of the future, "everything...was imported--building materials... furniture and clothing, diamond jewelry, champagne, and cigars" (Pendle, 1960:148). In the nitrate enclaves, the ‘ pleasures of the—day flowed in while the wealth of the future flowed out. The dominance of mineral export and finished goods im- port in the three legged Chilean table produced a class structure and a set of political forces which the re- emergence of copper in the twentieth century modified but also strengthened. It took an external crisis, the depres- sion of the 1930's and the collapse of Chilean exports to topple the table (Sunkel, 1965:121-122; Pinto, 1965:9-12). The existence of the Chilean mineral wealth in nineteenth century made possible the absorption and consolidation of 209 new upper class elements during the 1830-1860 period, a process which contributed greatly to the relative stability of Chilean society when compared to other nations of Spanish America (Pike, 1963:5—6). Thus, the division in the ruling class between Pipiolos and Pelucones (liberals and conserva- tives) which defined Chilean politics into the twentieth century did not prevent most presidents from completing their ten year terms. At the same time, the stability and flexibility provided by mineral export earnings was an im- portant source of elite hegemony and confidence in their ability to govern which later facilitated the emergence of a greater degree of formal democracy. By the end of the 1800's, Chilean prosperity had also begun to create a middle class, and the Old elite/mass model of society was no longer applicable (Huelin, 1968:468-470). It was not, however, the middle class which formed the in- dustrial bourgeoisie in Western Europe or the United States but instead was based on international commerce, the import and export of goods and services. That is to say that it was a pre-industrial middle class, one dependent on the continued success of Chilean mineral exports. This depen— dence was often direct, through employment as clerks, ac- countants, or supervisory personnel (empleados) in the min- eral industries themselves or at one step removed, through positions in the import/export firms centered in Santiago and Valparaiso. The mineral industry was also the basis of a middle sector whose dependence was indirect but no less 210 real. As the revenue figures in Table 6 suggest, the state bureaucracy was increasingly financed through taxation of nitrate exports. In sum, while the origins of a pre- industrial urban middle class in Chile lie in the mineral economy and metropole oriented social structure of the colo- nial period, the expansion of silver, copper, and nitrate production in the nineteenth century facilitated the growth of this class and firmly tied its interests to commercial and state activities (Petras, 1970:25-30; Veliz, 1965:3-4; Veliz, 1969:9-10). By the late 1880's, Chile had the highest per capita income in Latin America, a mineral base to pro- vide a surplus for investment, a rising middle class with some reform interests, and a ruling class with the self confidence necessary for national progress. From at least one angle of vision, Chile appeared to be on the way to national stability, economic growth, and political autonomy. Yet there were some clouds in the horizon, some aspects of Chilean history already manifest by the end of the nine- teenth century which suggest the contradictions in the Chilean path of development, contradictions which were the roots of stagnation in the next century. First, there was the question of industrial deve10pment. While it is often suggested that Latin American efforts at industrialization took the form of "forced" import substitution as a result of the 1930's depression, Chile's first attempts occurred a half century earlier. In the 1880's, concern over the drastic ups and downs of an "outward developing" economy 211 Spurred efforts by several groups within Chile to implement "spontaneous" (indigenously induced) import substitution industrialization (ECLA, 1966:7-8). Import substitution in this period was organized around the production of food- stuffs, textiles, and export linked industries. President Jose Manual Balmaceda's attempt to carry out a national in— dustrialization program in the early 1890's represents the culmination of these first efforts. His overthrow in 1893 by the three legs of the Chilean table indicates that the structuring of underdevelopment had already begun in Chilean society. That is to say that the internal structural ob- stacles to development were already aligned with the exter— nal restraints on development (Frank, 1969:73-82; ECLA, l966c:8). I Second, and inseparable from the above, there was the problem of Chile's place in the world economy. The country was already strongly tied to a single metropole, Britain, which had replaced Spain soon after independence (Pike, 1963: 7). Sources of export earnings remained the crucial deter- minant of Chilean well-being, and the important nitrate deposits had come under British control after being developed by Chileans. COpper, the other major mineral resource, was declining and already vulnerable to foreign penetration. Third, there was the problem of the relationship be- tween the mineral export sector and the rest of Chilean society. As noted above, the revenues from government tax- ation and the wages of employees were the chief linkages 212 between nitrate mining and Chile, and, while the revenues from exports rose, the revenues from taxation on the lati- fundios was falling. The government's ability to tax some of the earnings of the export sector lessened the political will to tax the classes which held power internally. Since nitrate extraction was actually organized across national economies, or more correctly as a part of the international political economy of Britain rather than along the lines of the Chilean political economy, many of the forward and back- ward linkages which might have been established were not. The middle class created on this export basis proved too weak to fulfill the role of innovating entrepreneurs and instead preferred to emulate the import-dependent consump- tion standards of the upper class. They also found a polit- ical alliance with the old ruling class more to their taste than the socially disruptive task of import substitution industrialization. Chile, then, despite appearances of well being in the statistics of the world market, was, in terms of the international class relations, actually well down the path of dependence, a situation in which the economy of certain coun- tries is conditioned by the development and ex- pansion of another economy to which the former is subjected. The relation of interdependence between two or more economies, and between these and world trade, assumes the form of dependence when some countries (the dominant ones) can ex- pand and be self starting, while other countries (the dependent ones) can do this only as a re- flection of that expansion, which can have either a positive or a negative effect on their immedi- ate development (Dos Santos, 1971:226). 213 II Immediately before us, at exactly the right time, just as we are ready for it, great Oppor- tunities for peaceful commercial and industrial expansion to the South are presented. Other in- vesting nations are already in the field--England, France, Germany, Italy, Spain; but the field is so vast, the new demands are so great, the prog- ress so rapid, that what other nations have done up to this time is but a slight advance in the race for the grand total... . The investment of American capital in South America under the direction of American eXports should be promoted, not merely upon simple invest- ment grounds, but as a means of creating and en- larging trade... --William Howard Taft, 1906 The opening years of the twentieth century marked a period of transition for Chilean copper, a transition shaped and directed by an accelerating and structurally changing demand for copper in the capitalist metropoles. This new demand for COpper was not experienced directly by Chile, however, but was mediated through the expansion of metropole- ~based mining cOrporations. The political economy of Chilean COpper which emerged from this period has remained a major, perhaps the major, determinant of Chilean underdevelopment for more than five decades. One way of summarizing this transition is as follows: during the 1871-1880 decade Chile reached its nineteenth century peak in COpper production, averaging 47.8 thousand metric tons per year (MT/Y), 36 percent of a world average of 129.4 thousand MT/Y. Chile's share was considerably more than the 15 percent each provided by Spain and the U.S., the second leading producers. Approximately 90 percent 214 of Chilean production during this decade came from several dozen Chilean owned mines. Three decades later, Chile's copper production had fallen by a third, averaging 32.5 thousand MT/Y while world production had increased over 450 percent to 727.3 thousand MT/Y. Chile's share of world out- put was less than 5 percent during this 1901-1910 decade. In 1918, Chile's copper production was 115.3 thousand MT/Y, more than double the nineteenth century peak, and repre- sented 8 percent of world output of 1,420.0 thousand MT/Y. The latter was already twice the average of a decade earlier. In this same year 87 percent of Chilean production was from foreign owned mines and fully 71 percent came from the two mines owned by subsidiaries of the U.S. based multinationals, Anaconda Company and Kennecott Copper Corporation.‘ By the early 1920's, approximately 70 percent of the copper con- sumed in the United States (which is broadly representative of world consumption) went to uses unknown during Chile's (peak production years of the preceding century. The chief sources of this new demand were the electrical industry, which accounted for 50 percent, and the automobile industry which consumed another 10-12 percent (particularly in rad- iators). In these same years, Chile's share of world pro- duction rose to around 15 percent, making her the second largest producer after the United States; and 90 percent of her output came from the mines of Anaconda and Kennecott. In the decades between the 1870's and World War I, the world COpper industry had been reorganized under the direction of 215 a handful of multinational corporations which mined, milled, smelted, refined, fabricated, and sold copper, along with a good half dozen by-product metals. United States based firms occupied a dominant position in this new international political economy of COpper, accounting for over three- fourths of world production by the end of World War I (ECLA, 1951:380; Reynolds, 1965:259; Skelton, 1937:385, 401, 405). To understand this reorganization of the Chilean copper industry, a closer look at COpper in the country which dis- placed Chile as the leading producer, the United States, is in order. The major problem facing Chilean and United States copper miners at the end of the nineteenth century was similar, the declining copper content of ores with the exhaustion of mines based on veins or native COpper. By 1900, the copper content of United States ores was down to less than Sopercent while few new deposits had been discov- ered since the rapid succession of major finds in the 1870's ' and 1880's (Bidwell, 1958:116). Technological advances in processing such as the convertor and the reverberatory fur- nace had already been introduced into United States mining practice, but these did not give United States miners a de- cisive lead over other producing areas (Davis, 1924:115- 124). The big breakthrough in COpper mining came in two stages: (1) the rise of electricity as an energy source and the subsequent development of electrolytic refining, and (2) the application of mass mining techniques to previously uneconomic deposits. 216 The theoretical basis for the use of electricity as an energy source extends back into the 1700's and Faraday's experiments date from 1830, but it was not until Edison lit up a part of New York City in 1882 that the potential of electricity began to unfold. The first commercial generating stations were opened in London, Milan and New York City in the 1880's; in 1892 copper wire linked New York and Chicago, signaling the displacement of steel as a conductor; in the same year, the General Electric Corporation was organized. Anaconda's construction of an electrolytic refinery, also in 1892, at Great Falls, Montana, was a crucial step in freeing the United States producers from dependence on Swansea as a smelting and refining center. Two years later, the United States exported more refined than unrefined COpper (McMahon, 1965:31; May, 1937:539-541; Richter, l927a:265-266, and 1927b:690-693). As copper stimulated electrification, so electricity aided in the production of COpper. It required the electrolytic refining process, developed during the 1870 and 1880's to produce copper of sufficient purity-- over 99.9 percentufrom low grade deposits to meet the de- mands of new industrial uses. At this level of purity, only one metal, aluminum, is superior for conducting elec- tric current. Electricity was only a part of the new technology of physics and chemistry develOped in the last third of the 1800's which dramatically widened the metropole/hinterland gap in the capitalist world. While disparities in standards 217 of living had existed in the past in conjunction with power differentials, by the end of the 1800's, the size of this gap was unprecedented (Rosenstein-Rodan, 1972:29-30). Hin- terland nations such as Chile failed to assimilate these new technologies not because of "traditionalistic value patterns," nor simply because of inadequate market size. There were, instead, two other reasons for Chile's failure to apply the new technologies to retain control over and develop their mineral resources, reasons which are typical of the fate of hinterland nations during this era. First was the structure Of dependency shaped by the colonial past. The three legged table of Chilean society would have tOppled if the institutional changes required for the absorption of metropolitan technology had occurred. Equally important, however, was the fact that the new technologies of potential abundance were implemented through the corporate economic form of the metropole. Thus, the "transfer of technology" occurred by way of an organizational structure which inte- grated the hinterland nations into the world economy in a subordinate role (Furtado, 1970:79-83; Skelton, 1937:379- 380). As this suggests, the solution to the problems of de- clining ore content in the United States copper mining in- dustry was not simply technological. To make use of the new technologies required organization, markets, and finan- cing on a scale hitherto unimagined outside of the rail- roads. In the capitalist metropoles, of course, this was 218 carried out under private auspices (although with state aid) and it is in the business organizations of this period that the roots of the modern multinational corporation can be found. The millions needed came from the great financiers of the day--the Morgans, Guggenheims, Harrimans-- while or- ganizational changes in the corporation required increasing separation of administrative and Operating functions within the firm (Chandler, 1961:1-18). During these same years, the metrOpole state financed the transportation networks which integrated national metropolitan markets and without which the corporation would have been unable to fulfill its potential for the emancipation of space-bound and time- bound people. For COpper, these general developments were brought together and applied by a United States mining engineer, Daniel C. Jackling. A failure in an earlier attempt at gold mining and a success as a metallurgist, Jackling got banker Charles Hayden and his Guggenheim associates to invest ten million dollars in the development of the Bingham Canyon mine near Garfield, Utah. NO new invention was involved, simply the organization of existing mining techniques on a mass basis, particularly the use of the steam shovel to remove the large amounts of ore and overburden found in all porphyry deposits.1 The mine came onstream in 1907 and the dividends had exceeded $204 million by 1930 (Fortune, 1930: 73-74; Pan American Union, 1952:3-4; Richter, 1927a:266-267; Wideman, 1965:265). 219 Yet the same pattern of business expansion which made possible production and sales for a national market also meant growth beyond national boundaries and the need to pro- duce for, and secure raw materials from, the world at large (Monthly_Review, 1969, Part 1:12—13). A transportation net- work that integrated national markets was extended to or- ganize international markets which focused on the capitalist metropoles. For copper, as for trade in many other raw ma- terials, it was the advances in steel production and ship- building which solved the technological obstacles to the integration of raw material producing hinterlands into the world economy (Furtado, 1970:79-83; Magdoff, 1968:33). In sum, in the last forty years of the nineteenth century there was created a . new pattern of economic relations in the world capitalist system. During the period from 1860 to 1900, three changes in the economic relations between nations are notable: (l) the number of commodities.entering international trade on a large scale multiplied greatly; (2) competition between many widely separated regions of the world first appeared or grew more intense; and (3) the standard of living of workers and the profitability of industry in European nations came to depend on the maintenance of overseas supplies, while the standard of living of the producers of raw materials came to depend on mar- ket fluctuations occurring sometimes on the other side of the world (Magdoff, 1969:32). It was in this context that United States entrepreneurs turned to Chile and acquired at extremely low cost, the most productive of the Chilean COpper mines. Boston had been the financial center of the early de- velopment of the U.S. copper industry, particularly the 220 Michigan deposits and it was two Bostonians, William Braden and A. C. Burrage, who brought Chilean copper under United States control. Using Guggenheim money, Braden acquired the Chilean mine E1 Teniente in 1904 and organized almost 100 claims into the Braden Copper Company incorporated the same year in Maine. In 1909 the Braden Copper Mines Company was organized in Delaware to be the sole stockholder of Braden Copper Company, now with 173 claims. Braden himself and four directors Of the Kennecott Mines Company, including two Guggenheims, were on the board of directors. The mine came onstream in 1912, using the mass mining techniques de- veloped in the United States, and in 1915 the newly organized Kennecott COpper Corporation acquired about 99 percent of Braden Copper Company along with several Alaskan properties including the Kennecott mine. Guggenheim and Morgan inter- ests have been represented on the board of Kennecott through- out its 58 years-of operation as they were on the board of its predecessor. In 1916, E1 Teniente was estimated to con- tain 219.7 million tons of 2.19 percent copper ore. Today, El Teniente is the largest underground COpper mine in the world and yearly output is exceeded only by two open pit mines, Bingham Canyon in Utah, also a Kennecott property, and Chuquicamata in Chile. A significant amount of gold, silver and molybdenum are extracted as by-products from E1 Teniente. In the mid 1960's, reserves were reported in excess of 1,700 million tons of 1.2 percent copper ore, al- though Kennecott mined ore throughout the decade which ran 221 between 1.7 percent and 1.9 percent (ECLA, 1970:146-148; Kennecott Annual Report, 1970:15; Moody's Manual of Railroads and Corporation Securities, 1911:3598; Moody's Manual of Railroads and Corporation Securities, 1917:2411-2413; Rich- ter, 1927b:706; Skelton, 1937:404; TNEC, 1940:453, 1008-1009). During these same years, A. C. Burrage, a director of Amalgamated Copper Company which then had controlling inter- est in Anaconda Copper Mining Company, acquired an Option on the largest Chilean mine and the largest copper mine in the world, Chuquicamata. Also working with Guggenheim money, he organized the Chile Exploration Company (incorporated in Delaware in 1911) and, after an investment of $100 million, production began in 1915. By 1918, Chuqui (as the mine is known in COpper circles) had surpassed the total Chilean output in the 1876 peak year of the nineteenth century. Six members of the Guggenheim family, four Burrages, and a rep— resentative of the Loeb banking family were among the direc- tors during the years when a 1920 estimate gave Chuqui 690 million tons of 2.12 percent COpper ore. With control divided and with extensive interests in other mineral ven- tures, the Guggenheims decided to put their controlling interest up for sale in the early 1920's. The result was consternation in the U.S. copper industry which at that time controlled three-fourths of world production. Cor- nelius Kelley and John D. Ryan, the two key figures in the consolidation Of Anaconda Company and the absorption of its Amalgamated Copper parent, went to Washington to discuss 222 the purchase of Chuqui. Ryan and Kelley argued that (1) domestic ores could not be expected to last forever and (2) that British interests would buy the mine if Americans failed to do so. The United States government agreed and Washington helped obtain the services of J. P. Morgan and Company as negotiator for the sale. In 1923, the Chile Ex- ploration Company, then valued at $180 million, was sold to Anaconda "at a tremendous profit" (Skelton, 1937:404). Ana- conda, which has remained loosly associated with Rockefeller interests, completed acquisition of Chile Exploration Com- pany by 1929 in a series of questionable maneuverings later investigated by the TNEC (Fortune, 1936a:91, 212, 214; Hend- ricks, 1922; Kolko, 1963:50-51; Poor's and Moodyfs Manual Consolidated, 1921:1775-1776; Moody's Industrials, 1926: 1971; Reynolds, 1965:217; TNEC, 1940:393, 700-701). After 42 years of output, in 1957, 686.2 million tons of ore had been removed; in-the mid 1960's reserves were reported at another 2,000 million tons of 1.25 percent COpper ore. In addition to being the world's largest copper mine in terms of output, Chuqui is also a major producer of sulfides, gold, and some silver (Davis, 1924:75, 79; ECLA, 1970:146- 148; Pan American Union, 1952:8-9). The third mine in the Gran Mineria has actually been operated as two separate mines. Among William Braden's 173 claims were several acquired in 1913 around Potrerillos, including a concession from the Chilean government for the construction of a railroad. In 1916, Anaconda organized 223 the Andes Copper Company (also incorporated in Delaware) to acquire these rights. The demand for COpper during World War I stimulated an initial investment of $60 million and production from sulfide ores began in 1926 and from oxide ores in 1928. The mine was estimated to contain 128.3 mil- lion tons of 1.49 percent copper ore at that time. By 1958, 200 million tons of ore had been removed. The oxide ores were exhausted in 1949 and the sulfide ores had only a de- cade of productive life remaining. In 1955, Andes acquired the adjacent Indio Muerto property and began an investment of $100.7 million in a mine called, appropriately enough, El Salvador. While a new crushing plant had to be construc- ted, El Salvador was close enough to Potrerillos for Andes to use most of the same railroad, the smelter, etc. Produc- tion began in 1959 and soon surpassed that of Potrerillos at its peak. The same mid 1960's survey estimated El Salvador to heve-350 million tons of 1.6 percent COpper ore. Like the rest of the Gran Mineria, Potrerillos and El Salvador produce significant amounts of gold, silver, and molybdenum as by-products (ECLA, 1970:147; Griffin, 1966: 153-156; United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:90; Moody's Manual of Railroads and Corporation Securities, 1917:2136; Poor's and Moody's Manual Consolidated, 1921:1059-1060; Moody's Industrials, 1936:662-663; Moody's Industrial Manual, 1956:2747). Taken together, these three mines compose the Gran Mineria, defined in 1955 as those mines producing 25,000 224 MT/Y or more and in 1966 as those producing at least 75,000 MT/Y. The Gran Mineria has accounted for over 85 percent, and often in excess of 95 percent, of Chilean COpper pro- duction and all the production under foreign control since World War I. Chile Exploration Company and Andes Mining Company, the largest and smallest Of the three respectively, account for 60-65 percent of the Gran Mineria output, while Braden COpper Company provides the remaining 35-40 percent. Figure 1 summarizes the international linkages in Chilean copper which existed prior to Chileanization in the late 1960's and/or nationalization in 1971. In concluding this section, I would like to point out some of the implications of the acquisition Of Chilean cop- per properties by United States multinationals for a re- curring debate over the role of foreign capital in raw ma- terial producing hinterlands. Those who argue that foreign sources of capital can make an important contribution to "economic deve10pment" Often base their claim on the assump- tion that "capital expenditures for exploration and develop- ment in mining and petroleum are large, have a long gesta- tion period, and involve a high degree of risk" (Mikesall, l97lbz26). Private investors from metropoles are seen as best able to assume this risk while hinterland governments are asked to limit themselves to infrastructural investment and administrative efforts. An alternative perspective sug- gests that it is at the level of finance and market access and control, rather than any ability to take risks, which 225 canon“: comm one .H ouomwm .uonumz xuao xuow 3oz ca axooo can .n.z .>onE< cuuom Ca apocawou m.mocoonc< can mummomw0uc< wo whom ocu com3uon umoooo can .ucoEdfioco .moooo COHuossmcoo .Hao Hocw mqudmcmuu .oo canmEmwum waficu .ocfluHOEm new who ooumuucoocoo mofluuwo can ooflocsm Oanosm 0» menu owouaflmm moaawuouuom ".00 omouaamm moHkumuuom one .00 manuscoum mHfi£088 .mwuocfi: coho 0:» mo upon uoz a .ouo wm.~ mcou COAHHHE ooa.a mo mw>uwmou co>oum “ocflE cocoon ocsoumuooc: umoouma m.cau03 "moccacoe Hm A-IIII. >cmoeou uwmdoo coomum All xcmdeoo umdmoo uuoooccox .eauo3 umaaauaaao on» ea ummcoo mo noosooum ummoumH 6cm “mama ca Amummmm sac COaumHOQAOO .m.D unwound enema “menaceozxooum new museum memmcmuu .muouoouwo >2 ooucomwudou mumououcH ammuoz can anncwooso aouuasm< 0A xcmdsoo ocacHz Ommaucmm acacOAuw< m4 .ouo mw.a mcou COAHHHE omm wo mm>ummou cw>0pd mmmaoomma "mmma coauosooua cofluOOUONQ comma "noon>acm Hm \ moHHHHOpuom xcomEOU menace: moccd A xcmmEOU cocoomcd ««.ou omouaflcm mOHHeuouuom .wuo wm~.~ mcou coHHHaE ooo.~ Mo mo>uommu cm>oum “Ausouso an. wade uocdoo unwound m.oauoz unucsm0w=csnu .oHuOI unaacu Iadmu onu cw wooaoo uo uoosoouo uncouoa “coca :w muommm xn sawumuoa nuou .m.: unwound sumed “mucuooufio one mucosa neumcouu ha owucmmouoou ...oo canmsmoum maazo mummumuna uoaaoumxoom xcmoEoo sewumuonxm mawno 226 metropole based multinationals defeated their hinterland rivals (Girvan, 1970:492). This perspective goes on to argue that, since foreign control produces distorted growth and a drain of surplus for investment, hinterland government would be well advised to develop their own mineral resources and attempt integration through several processing levels. While the second issue in the debate cannot be answered at this point, it is clear that, whatever may be the general case (and many more specific studies need to be done) the case of copper certainly supports the latter position and Chile is perhaps the strongest example. By the end of the nineteenth century, the location of all the major porphyry deposits of COpper in the western hemisphere were well known. Only the low ore content made these deposits uneconomical for working by the labor inten- sive methods in use at the time. The rich surface veins of E1 Teniente, for-examp1e, had been worked since the eigh- teenth century when it was supposedly discovered by a Spanish lieutenant (hence the name El Teniente). The mine was a major producer from 1819 until 1897 when the decline in ore content forced a cessation of Operations. The same was also true for Chuquicamata, worked even in pre-conquest times. Thus, William Braden and A. C. Burrage did not "explore," invest "risk" capital and reap the rewards due the private investor who defeats his competitors in open competition. 227 As was the case for the huge Bingham Canyon porphyry deposit in Utah, successful deve10pment required no new in- ventions. All that was needed was the coordination of existing mining techniques and the use of steam power on the scale necessary to remove the vast amounts of ore--often 100 tons for every 1 ton of COpper--and overburden found in porphyry deposits. This meant, first and foremost, access to vast accumulations of capital, provided at first by the commercial banks and later generated internally by the mining companies themselves. Second, there was the neces- sity of a large and growing market which could absorb the large output necessary to make a profit beyond the high overhead expenses of prophyry mining. This was made pos- sible by the electrification and automobilization of the metropoles (Fortune, 1930:3-4; Herfindahl, 1959:213ff; May, 1937:541-550; Reynolds, 1965:215-216: Richter, 1927b:705). Nor do our protagonists fit the mold Of the small risk-taking entrepreneurs of classical economics. The cop- per industry was already fairly concentrated and the leading firms established. Anaconda and Kennecott, or their prede- cessors, have been the two largest producers in the world every year from 1912 to the present. Their share of world production has fluctuated between 27 percent and 41 percent (Herfindahl, 1959:165). Anaconda had already been the major factor in one effort at monopolization of the industry on a world scale, the Amalgamated Pool of 1899-1901, an attempt by Standard Oil and U.S. Steel interests to create a paral- lel firm in the COpper industry. Even as early as the 228 collapse of the Secretan Corner of 1887-1889, Anaconda, along with Calumet and Hecla, was strong enough to force EurOpean bankers to unload their accumulated COpper stock slowly enough to prevent disruption of the market. Similarly, by no stretch of the imagination can the Guggenheims or the Morgans be seen as sources of risk capital for independent small investors. Thus, the achievement of control over Chilean COpper can best be described as the accumulation of advantages on the part of oligopolistic corporations which were already beginning to integrate across processing levels and political boundaries. In addition, it required state action to make the acquisitions economically viable. With- out the United States-instigated Panamanian "revolution" and the completion of the Panama Canal in 1914, Chilean cop- per would have been a much less desirable investment for metropole firms. The Canal cut the distance to the companies' refineries on the East Coast of the U.S. by 40 percent and the distance to West European ports by one-third. In an era when the COpper consumption of the United States, Germany, France and the United Kingdom was over 75 percent of the world total, this was a significant saving. ‘The possibility of State action of this nature ane state social investment on this scale was of course, limited to a very few metropole governments. In this hemisphere, only Washington was capable of such a venture. In sum, less elegantly but more eloquent— ly, the success of Anaconda andeennecott is simply a case of "them that as, gets" (May, 1937:547-549; McMahon, 1965: 32-33; Moon, 1926:424-428; Skelton, 1937:395-398, 505). 229 NOTES 1 Porphyry copper deposits are large bodies of ore with low, usually less than 3-4 percent, copper content in which the copper is evenly distributed throughout rather than ap- pearing in the form of veins or as native metal. These de- posits constitute the basic resource of the twentieth century COpper industry. CHAPTER 7 THE APPROPRIATION OF ACTUAL ECONOMIC SURPLUS Underdevelopment is an unemployed worker looking through a glass store window at a tele— vision set showing an airline commercial. --Salvador Allende, 1970 In this section, I analyze the mechanisms by which the copper mining multinationals appropriate the actual economic surplus generated by the Chilean economy. For a variety of reasons, it is difficult, if not impossible, to arrive at definitive figures for the amounts involved, and in some cases any pretense at exactness is simply wishful thinking. It would be helpful to have unrestricted access to company records for comparison with official data, but such is not likely to occur. In several cases I have been forced to rely on descriptive material. Thus, the conclusions ar- rived at in this section are subject to revision. There is, however, sufficient information available to sketch the outlines of the international relationships of surplus ap- propriation within the copper industry. Even with the above limitations, the results are both startling and so— bering. Before examining these mechanisms at length, however, it is necessary to outline, in greater detail than was pos- sible in the introduction, the reasons for focusing on 230 231 copper in any analysis of the Chilean path of deve10pment in the twentieth century. Although it is an accepted fact that copper has an important place in the Chilean economy, many writers prOpose a national, or internal, explanation for Chilean stagnation. Those who take this approach often go on to argue that, while COpper is not the key sector in Chilean deve10pment, its contribution has been positive,’ largely as a result of the policies of the copper companies and despite misguided nationalism on the part of Chilean administrations. The following points form the core of this argument: (1) The size of the mining sector as a whole and the employment it generated made it the key factor in Chilean deve10pment until the end of the 1920's when min- eral exports amounted to 23 percent of GDP. Since that time, however, depression-induced import substitution in- dustrialization has made industry the leading sector while agriculture is a.retarding sector. This has also meant that (2) mining and quarrying, which includes coal, nitrate, and COpper mines not part of the Gran Mineria, has declined as a portion of GDP. (3) The labor force in mining has also declined in relative terms and employment in the large cop- per companies has declined in absolute terms. (4) Further, while the profits of the copper companies have risen in recent years, they do not amount to a substantial portion of Chilean GDP; therefore (5) Chile should avoid over-taxing the Gran Mineria, which discourages reinvestment and in- creased output, and (6) should concentrate on policies which 232 provide incentives for the companies to establish linkages with the Chilean economy through their purchasing policies. Finally (7) COpper mining cannot be counted on to have a large impact on national integration and growth since it fails to do so even in areas such as Utah and Montana in the United States (Amunategue, 1968; Mamalakis, 1971; Mikesall, 1971a; and Silvert, 1965 all make one or more of these points). In a nutshell, my response to these arguments is as follows: While there is some validity to these points taken separately, as a whole they obscure and/or deny the most significant facts about Chilean.copper: its unique poten- tial as a source of actual (and potential) economic surplus for Chilean development, and the loss of that surplus. through the international organization of the industry. (1) While it is true that the mining sector has declined as a proportion of GDP and a source of employment, the use of these figures alone understates COpper's significance even in statistical terms. Past government policies have pro- duced some linkages, albeit limited ones, between copper and the rest of the economy. Therefore, some employment and output in manufacturing and agriculture along with a considerable portion of commerce and transportation are dependent on the Gran Mineria. (2) Further, the linking of the Gran Mineria to the Chilean political economy largely through taxation means that a substantial portion of the state based middle class owes its well being to the Gran 233 Mineria. Thus, import substitution industrialization, which has progressed little since the mid 1950's anyway (Furtado, 1970:86-87), has simply made more complex the ties of dependence but has not broken them. (3) Since copper continues to provide an increasing portion of export earn- ings (manufactured exports are declining) and thus serves as a "substitute" for a capital goods sector (Mamalakis, 1971), further progress in industrialization remains heavily dependent on COpper earnings. In a dependent, export- oriented society, there is a fairly inflexible structure of necessary imports if import substitution industrialization is to continue. (4) As suggested in the second point, cop- per is an important source of government revenue. Thus, a government not beholden to the state—based middle class for political support could potentially use these revenues for the type of social consumption and investment expenditures that would socialize both the hardships and the benefits of the deve10pmental process. The hardships, as is charac- teristic of capitalist development, have long been social- ized but not so the benefits. '(5) The high labor produc- tivity of the work force in the Gran Mineria, anywhere from two to four times that of other sectors (Weaver, 1968:133- 134), means that it must continue to provide a major share of surplus for investment. (6) The international organiza- tion of the Chilean copper industry in the form of the mul- tinationals means an appreciable loss of this surplus. (7) Finally, COpper mining can and should make an important 234 contribution to national integration and growth through ex- tensive linkages. The correct comparison here is not copper in Chile with employment, taxes, and linkages of copper in Utah or Southwest Montana but rather with copper in the United States. Non-ferrous metals rank high in terms of linkages in the latter case (OECD, 1969:17). Table 7, on the following page, presents some of the important histor- ical data on the place of mining, COpper, and the Gran Mineria in the Chilean political economy. This debate raises several issues, one of the most im- portant of which is the problem of comparison. To what should the amount of actual economic surplus extracted by the COpper companies be compared in order to assess the significance of the sums involved? Since the question is one of Chilean growth, actual and potential, the relevant numerator is not the total gross national (or domestic) product or total-national income. Rather, the actual eco- nomic surplus appropriated should be juxtaposed with the amount of actual economic surplus available for investment by Chileans. It is the latter, as argued in Chapter 1, rather than the size of GNP, GDP, NI, etc. which is the key to growth. Actual economic surplus available for invest- ment can be approximated by net private and public capital formation, gross domestic capital formation financed through savings, or the total after tax returns to corporate capital plus central government revenues. Each of these measures has some advantages and disadvantages. Generally, however, 2235 .muHumHumum momma HmcoHumcuwucH mo xoooummm .mcoHumz owuHca HomommH pom mmmH "mnmummmH .«qum "mva can mNmH .m .Hou x H .Hou mo mmsHm> musHOmnm >3 pmHHaHuHsE umddoo mo moHua m.umo:poua .m.: . .moHumHumum uonmq HmcoHumcuwucH mo xoonumw» .OAH Eoum pmumHsonu "wwommH uonmuHmmH .dqum Eouw owumHsono uovanoMaH .muHumHumum unsoood HmcoHumz mo xoonumwm .mcoHumz nmuHca Eouu nmumHsonu "uwmmmH uHmmnHmmH .aqom EOuw kumHonmU "ommHummaH .ma .oz .mwuoz oHEocoom wHHLU .Ommou "onaH “mmHuoomH .ckuHuo Eoum mmenmva u .Npooz mo mmsmmH pwuomHmm new H .Hoo Eoum pmumHsonU uovauonH .ummmoo mo mmome ucm>mHmu Eouw pmumHsono oumHaommH ummHnmmmH .Hcmchmum: ummmHumHmH .mm .02 .mmuoz oHEocoom mHch .ommoo "oan umlewvH HommH .mqom "monnome uommuommummmH .dqom “mmmHuommH MHmmuommnHmmH .4H0m "mvaIOHaH uh .HOU "m .HOU "m .HOU “v .HOU um .HOU "N .HOU "H .Hou "mmousom .mwmuw>m mvalmme n “mmmH n "mmmum>m mmmHlmmmH n “mmmH n vamH n uvmmH n umwomum>m umm> m>Hu u n o I . m w m m H om n.m o.m o.HH n.an MH 5mm oan mo m.m v.oH v.mm MH vmm mme mm o.HH m.m m.m H.om mH «mm ome Nu «.mH. o.m 7 m.om mH mmv mmmH H Hm o.m H.v . m.mH m.mm mom ommH v hm m.m m.oH m.m¢ Hm owe mva h H m.HH m.m n.mH o.mm mom cva Hm m.m m.VH m.~a mH mom mmmH o H o.m m.m n.5H «.mm . omm omoH mm H.n m.o~ o.mm VH NoH mmoH m . . m H m.om mm onH m.nm v mm mHmH H 0.0 mm OHmH muuomxm cmmHHco moo Mo w mm mchHz moo coo mHumcH: coho uqmuso Amcoa oHuum: paw» m mm HmEuom coHu0500um CH mouom IHHLU mo w m EOum usauso “mamou UHHOZ oocv :oHuusc HHuumso cmeHLU w umHHmuHamo uoum umdmou uo msHm> can qucHz mo w mm won 1&00 cmmHHnu chmHnonH mHumcHz :muu ecu can .uwmaou .mchHz :meHAU mo mHom mcu co mousmmwz pmuomHmm .n mHnma 236 statistics for gross domestic capital formation financed through savings are the most readily available and thus I will use these in most instances. One final point: when making comparisons of this sort, it is all too easy to forget that while, in and of them- selves, numbers are neutral, each statistic is an expression of some facet of many lives. Lives which might be different-- better nourished, more healthy, happier--if less of the fruits of Chilean labor were appropriated by United States multi- nationals. Simply as a reminder of this reality, Table 8 is included to suggest some of the dimensions of Chilean under- development and stagnation. Again, there is the problem of what to compare with Table 8. Rather than debate this issue at length, I will leave it with this: in 1970, the presi- dent of Anaconda, Frank Milliken, received $225,000 in sal- ary alone. -From all reports, Mr. Milliken and his family appear in good health--no distended bellies, no children dying in infancy--and probably consume the United States average of over 3,100 calories a day, an average that in- cludes an amount of animal protein which, by itself, exceeds the total Chilean protein consumption per day. Finally, most of the directors of Anaconda have already outlived the Chilean life expectancy of 50-55 years. Drawing on studies of multinational corporations in general and of mining multinationals in particular, I have been able to identify four primary mechanisms by which mul- tinationals appropriate the actual economic surplus generated 237 Table 8. Some Measures of Chilean "Underdevelopment" Income Distribution: Chile 1948 1960 8 Population % Income % Population % Income 33.4 5.8 31.7 5.6 12.6 5.4 18.3 10.0 42.5 46.6 37.3 40.8 9.1 25.4 10.7 29.9 2.4 16.8 2.0 13.7 Average Annual Increase in Cost of Living: Chile 1940-1944 1945-1949 1950-1954 1955-1959 1960-1964‘ 1965-1969 16.3% 18.6% 31.2% 45.8% 24.7% 25.4% Infant Mortality Rate 1948 1956 1963 1966 Chile 147.0 112.3. 105.4 127.5 Food Production Per Capita: Chile (1952-1956:100) 1953 1955 1960 1963 1966 1969 99 103 97 100 92 90 Daily Per Capita Calories: Chile Grammes of Protein Per Day: Chile Pre-WWII 1954-1956 1964—1966 Pre-WWII 1964-1966 2,250 2,540 2,520 69.6 65.4 Sources: Income distribution 1948 and 1960 from ECLA, l966a. Infant mortality rates from United Nations, 1958 and 1968. Food production per capita from FAO, 1970. Calories and protein per capita from FAO, 1962 and 1971. Cost of living from United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960; Furtado, 1970; ECLA, 1970. 238 by hinterland economies. Some of these mechanisms have ap- plication chiefly to mining multinationals but in all cases it is the integration of the multinational corporation which makes surplus apprOpriation possible. This integration takes two forms, (1) vertical, i.e., across levels of pro- cessing and manufacture, and (2) geographical, i.e., across national boundaries. In the first case, the outcome is the internalization of profits from different stages of produc- tion and the resulting difficulty of national efforts at regulation, taxation, and control of multinationals. In the second case, the result is a class between national priorities in factor organization and the profit priorities of the mul- tinational corporation which organizes factors across sev- eral nations. In short, a national political economy versus the political economy of a multinational corporation (Girvan, 1970: O'Connor, l970a; Penrose, 1971b; Rollins, 1970). The most obvious form of surplus apprOpriation arises from the geographical integration of the multinational and appears in the statistics of international capital flows between parent and branches or subsidiaries. Thus, United States based multinationals have produced a net inflow of private capital in every year since World War II, while multiplying the book value of their assets by a factor of 10 during the same period. (See relevant issues of U.S., Dept. of Commerce, Survey of Current Business.) Of partic- ular significance here is the fact that, when disaggregated by metrOpole and hinterland nations, there is a net outflow 239 to the former and a net inflow from the latter great enough to produce an overall net inflow despite the greater book value of United States investments in other metropoles. By the end of the 1960's this surplus on the private account had become the largest single positive contribution to U.S. balance of payments (Ackerman and MacEwan, 1972:31; Multif national Corporation and the World Economy, 1973:33). For an individual hinterland nation, unless new foreign invest- ment continues indefinately at an accelerating rate, a very unlikely occurrence, the outflow in repatriated profits on any given amount of foreign investment will eventually ex- ceed the gains from foreign exchange, savings through de- creased imports, and increased exports, government taxation, etc.(Zweig, 1973). I It has proved impossible to obtain data on capital flows between the U.S. and Chile for the COpper companies alone. There are some general indicators of magnitude however: A source sympathetic to the companies states that Anaconda's net investment in Chuquicamata and the Potrerillos/El Salva- dor complex amounted to $93 million between 1930 and 1965, while the profits between 1945 and 1969 were $810 million on Chuquicamata alone (Gall, 1972:l). Another source re- ports that U.S. mineral multinationals--c0pper, iron, and nitrate--have received $10.8 billion in earnings on their Chilean operations during the 1910-1970 decades (NACLA, 1972:107). This sum exceeded the total Chilean GNP in 1970 by approximately 35 percent. This outflow has meant 240 increasing balance of payments pressures on Chile, partic- ularly during the 1960's. During 1965-1969, the yearly deficit for "compensation for employees and property and entrepreneurial'income" (most of which represented payments to the copper multinationals and their employees) in the external transactions of the Chilean economy was greater than the total yearly deficit on current transactions for the same years (UN, Yearbook of National Accounts Statistics, 1970:209). Chile ended the decade with one of the highest per capita levels of external debt in the world, debt in- curred at least partially to finance these balance of pay- ments deficits. During the 1958-1968 decade, service pay- ments on foreign capital averaged 45 percent of export in- come and exceeded 50 percent for 1963-1965 and 1968 (ECLA, 1972:84-85). Although figures are not available for the copper com- panies alone, there are yearly statistics on capital flows for all United States companies with investments in mining and smelting in Chile. Table 9, on the next page, presents the information for 1950-1970. An examination of Moody's, company reports, and assorted documents indicates that the investments of Anaconda Company and Kennecott COpper Corpor- ation represent at least 90 percent of the total U.S. in- vestment in mining and smelting. Thus, these figures closely approximate the operations of the copper multinationals. Chile appears as a paradigm case of the general tendency outlined previously. In all years except 1953, the profit ' 241 Table 9. U.S. Direct Long Term Investment in Mining and Smelting in Chile (All figures in million $) * = $500,000 Year End Book Value Profits From All Mining & Capital Flow From Reinvested Subsidiary Year Industries Smelting‘ Parent to Subsidiary Earnings To Parent 1970 748 445 25 -22 62 1969 847 452 —l42 26 108 1968 964 586 78 —8 131 1967 878 517 17 -4 129 1966 844 494 -14 -l 98 1965 829 509 9 * 56 1964 788 499 -5 1 60 1963 768 503 -1 * 48 1962 768 504 4 l 52 1961 725 503 -14 * 43 1960 738 517 -10 * 58 1959 729 526 29 3 63 1958 687 498 24 4 32 1957 666 483 27 3 41 1956 682 454 31 2 83 1955 643 421 2 1 61 1954 635 418 —34 * 31 1953 660 452 26 2 17 1952 626 423 39 2 43 1951 585 382 30 2 45 1950 540 351 _11 1 33 1950-1970 totals: 138 15.5 1,294 1960-1970 totals: -53 -5 , 845 Total net transfer of funds from Chile to the U.S., 1950-1970:. 1,173.5 Sources: 1961—1970 from United States, Dept. of Commerce, Survey of Cur- rent Business. 1950-1960 from United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1963. 242 flow from subsidiary to parent exceeded both the reverse flow and the sum of the reverse flow plus reinvested earnings. In 18 of the 21 years, repatriated profits were at least 50 percent greater than the sum of reinvested earnings and cap- ital flows from parent to subsidiary while in 14 of the years, repatriated profits were at least double the latter sum. There are also some other interesting patterns. First, the rate of reinvestment is incredibly low, a fact admitted by even those writers sympathetic to the companies (Mamalakis, 1971:413). While the investments of U.S. multinationals in mining and smelting accounted for more than 85 percent of the repatriated profits during the 1950-1970 period, they provided less than 70 percent of the capital flow from par- ent to subsidiary and less than 10 percent of the reinvested earnings during the same years. Despite this low rate, the book value of United States investment in mining and smelting increased by over 60 percent between 1950-1968. The type of investment which did occur was generally geared towards a quick recovery of capital in a national political environ- ment which seemed increasingly threatening to foreign con- trol of the Gran Mineria. During 1969 and 1970, the book value of U.S. investment in mining and smelting fell by al- most a quarter. Anaconda and Kennecott were evidently wor- ried about the 1970 elections and the threat of a leftist victory. In fact, in 1969, the companies removed $224 mil- lion, an amount equal to a per capital contribution of over $22 by Chileans to the U.S. 243 A second striking fact is the tremendous drain on the Chilean economy which occurred throughout the 1960-1970 years. Total reinvested earnings are negative for this period as is the flow from parent to subsidiary. On the average, over $85 million was extracted each year, more than $10 a year on a per capita basis for the entire period. This pattern of surplus appropriation during the 1960's raises some fascinating questions which are not answerable from publicly available information. Did the companies re- sent Frei's Chileanization program and, despite their greater fear of a U.P. nationalization effort, attempt to sabatoge it in the hope of a reversal by a future rightist govern- ment? Had they simply decided to write off Chile as a long term investment and attempted to take out as much as pos- sible as quickly as possible? Or were their investments in Chilean COpper so fabulously profitable that, once the re- placement and modernization investment foregone during World War II had occurred, the rates of return in the 1960's could be expected to continue indefinitely? Whatever the case may be, the behavior of the copper companies differed from that of other U.S. investors. In sectors other than mining and smelting, repatriated profits exceeded reinvested earn- ings plus new capital flows by "only" 15 percent, a gap which shows no variation between the two decades. How do these absolute figures compare to the actual economic surplus available to Chile for investment? Two ways of approaching this question are summarized in Table 10. 244 Table 10. Two Measures of Chilean Loss of Actual Economic Surplus Through U.S. Investment in Mining and Smelting (Million $) Funds Transferred as % of Gross Domestic Net Transfer Funds Transferred as Investment from Govt., of Funds from a % of Gross Private Public & Private Year Chile to U.S. Fixed Investment Corporations Savings 1950 15 14.0 54.0 1951 13 12.3 40.2 1952 2 2.0 8.6 1953 -11 ---- negative savings 1954 64.5 70.4 negative savings 1955 58 65.0 48.7 1956 50 33.3 36.8 1957 11 6.8 3.5 1958 4 2.8 3.8 1959 31 13.9 11.4 1960 67.5 31.6 28.8 1961 56.5 23.3 17.5 1962 47 37.1 40.3 1963 48.5 32.5 23.5 1964 64 30.3 20.9 1965 46.5 20.2 13.4 1966 113 41.8 23.7 1967 116 43.8 25.5 1968 61 22.2 12.9 1969 224 74.1 37.0 1970 57 16.4 10.4 Average 1950-1970: 28.3 Average 1950-1970: 24.2 1950-1959: 22.0 1950-1959: 25.9 1960-1970: 33.9 1960-1970: 23.1 Sources: Col. 1: Calculated from Table 9 by adding Col. 3-5. Col. 2: Col. 1 and ECLA's five year averages. Col. 3: Calculated from Col. 1 and Pan American Union, America en Cifras. 245 In this table I have used the net flow of capital between Chile and the United States (from Chile to the U.S. in all years except 1953) since this amount represents the actual loss of surplus. (In terms of loss of control over the actual economic surplus, however, a case can be made for in- cluding repatriated profits, reinvested earnings, and net capital flows from subsidiary to parent.) The first mea- sure in the table compares the amount of repatriated profits with the total gross private fixed investment and shows the same pattern noted in Table 9 of a discontinuity between the 1950's and the 1960's. While the overall average was 28.3 percent, during 1960-1970 Chile could have increased her gross private investment by one-third if she controlled the profits from the Gran Mineria. This comparison understates the impact for two reasons: (1) some of the private fixed investment that did occur was done by Andes, Braden, and Chile Exploration Company and thus the comparison between surplus lost and Chilean private fixed investment is under- stated; (2) more importantly, gross private fixed investment includes both net investment and replacement but it is only the former which can legitimately be considered part of the surplus. If figures for net private fixed investment were available, the percentage lost through capital flows to U.S. mining multinationals would be much greater, perhaps well over 50 percent. As in most dependent capitalist societies, the Chilean state has been increasingly important as a source of invest- ment; thus, a comparison with private investment, gross or 246 net, does not include all investment. In the Chilean case, private investment has accounted for only about 50 percent of gross domestic capital formation since 1950 (ECLA, 1951, 1965, 1966b, 1967, and 1970). Using figures for gross domes- tic capital formation would again involve double counting since some portion of the depreciation financed investment would come from the COpper companies. Figures are available on the total gross domestic capital formation financed by public and private savings, however, and they are the basis for the second measure in Table 10. Savings by private house- holds have been excluded since, with the exception of 1950 and 1953, there has been dissaving in this sector. While the yearly rates of surplus loss on this measure fluctuate, in each decade investment could have been increased by about a quarter. Once again there is some understatement involved since part of the saving represents that of Andes, Braden and Chile Exploration Company. Even with these rough mea- sures, it is clear that the potential gain to Chile through control over the surplus generated by the Gran Mineria is considerable. During the pre-WWII period, when taxation on the Gran Mineria was lower (between 1913 and 1924, Braden Copper Company returned only 0.8 percent of its total sales by way of taxation to the Chilean government) and the Chilean surplus was smaller, the proportion of surplus lost through capital flows to the U.S. must have been considerably greater. Despite their impressive size, the statistics of capi- tal flows from Chile to the U.S. represent only a part of 247 the loss of Chilean surplus. A second mechanism of surplus appropriation is rooted in the division of labor within the multinational corporation. To grasp this requires a recog- nition of the ideological function of the word "multination- al," a term which evokes an image of an equal partnership among several nations. DeSpite this label, however, almost all the major multinationals are controlled by stockholders/ management/directors in the nation where their headquarters are located (Monthlpreview, 1969, Part I:3-4). Virtually the only exceptions to this rule are Royal Dutch Shell and Unilever, where control is truly shared between Dutch and British capital. These two corporations are among the earliest multinationals, however, and their example has not been widely followed. It is also worth pointing out that these two firms are binational between two of the oldest capitalist metropoles. There is still no publicly known example of a multinational where control is shared between metrOpole and hinterland nationals. Since the headquarters of multinational corporations are not randomly distributed throughout the capitalist world (I have seen no list of multinationals which includes any from Latin America, Asia except Japan, or Africa except South Africa), control is thus concentrated in the capitalist metropoles. The result is a structure in which the functional division of labor is organized on a national basis (Chandler and Redlich, 1961: 115-120: Hymer, 1972b:122-125).. The head offices in the metropole administer the Operational units in the hinter- lands. The tasks of administration include the allocation 248 of financial resources, the determination of output, the raising of additional capital through sales of stocks and bonds, the determination of what technical expertise should be developed for the operation of the corporation, and con- trol over its distribution and use at the various levels of the firm. The appropriation of Chilean surplus as a result of this structure is probably impossible to quantify, there- fore, I shall use examples in order to demonstrate this mechanism. As a first case, for a Chilean national to ac- quire stock in one of the COpper companies whose actions were so crucial to the Chilean nation involved a transfer of funds out of Chile to the U.S. Andes Copper Company, Braden Copper Company, and Chile Exploration Company were all at least 99 percent owned by Anaconda or Kennecott, leaving little room for any influence from Chilean stock- holders. Furthermore, Andes and Chile were each listed on the New York but not the Santiago stock exchange. Similar- ly, the two parent corporations, in which there is a large amount of public stock trading, were listed on the New York and San Francisco exchanges and sold informally in other major U.S. cities, but again, were not available on the Santiago exchange. Thus, Chileans who wished to purchase stock in these companies had to go through a U.S. stock ex- change which meant fees to U.S. brokers and transfer agents, all of which involved payments to U.S. nationals and which represented an outflow of funds from Chile. This outflow 249 was a drain on Chilean surplus since money invested in U.S. stock could hardly be expected to further Chilean develop- ment, nor would that paid to U.S. brokers. The sums involved would undoubtedly be small when com- pared to the repatriation of profits; however, total U.S. receipt of royalties and fees during the 1960-1970 period amounted to $17 billion, ten times the U.S. outflow on this item. In 1970, the U.S. received a $2.5 billion contribu- tion to its balance of payments in the form of royalties and fees (Multinational Corporation: A Compendium of Papers, 1973:37-38). None of this is to argue that it would have been a social benefit to Chile for Anaconda and Kennecott to have been listed on the Santiago Stock Exchange, thus en- couraging stockholding in the COpper companies bythe. Chilean ruling class. This "reform," along with analogous ones such as the promotion of indigenous managers to the head office (Turgenhadt, 1971:193-202), would simply repre- sent a neo-colonial consolidation of the alliance between metropole and hinterland ruling classes (Galtung, 1970:81). Nonetheless, while the benefits from these reforms would have been class linked, the losses from the actual situation were socialized through the appropriation of the Chilean surplus by the mining multinationals. The international division of labor along functional lines which is internal to the multinational also delineated channels of actual economic surplus appropriation which did not appear in the national accounts but were instead entered 250 as costs of production for the Chilean subsidiaries of Anaconda and Kennecott. For example, since the higher level of skilled personnel are concentrated in the metropole, the operation of the Chilean mines remained dependent on metro- pole technological expertise. Thus, when significant bot- lenecks or breakdowns occurred at Chuqui, engineers were flown from New York City to handle the problems. The ex- pense incurred was entered as an overhead cost for the Chile Exploration Company and they had to repay the amount involved to Anaconda (Gall, 1972:7—8). This repayment would not, of course, appear under remitted profits. A cost it was, but hardly a socially necessary one. Instead this is a striking example of an international class structure in which surplus is apprOpriated from the productive facilities of the hin- terland to support the creation of a professional class in the metropole. Indeed, this international class structure received explicit recognition in the wage and salary pattern of the Chilean subsidiaries. Each of these companies had what was known as a "gold roll," professional and technical contract employees who earned their salaries in dollars (Gall, 1972:2). These employees numbered over 1,000 by the early 1960's when they constituted about 6 percent of the labor force in the Gran Mineria. They were also the per- sonnel who could hope for a future, and whose loyalty lay, with Anaconda and Kennecott, not just Andes, Braden, or Chile. Payment in dollars oriented them towards this future, gave them privileged access to imported consumer goods 251 (avoiding the discriminatory exchange rates designed to re- tain some of the surplus in Chile), and thus served as a further drain on the Chilean surplus. Evidently, one of the responses of the COpper multinationals to the efforts of nationalists to control their operations was to expand this miniature center in the hinterland since the gold roll proportion of the Gran Mineria labor force doubled between 1940 and 1960. As all class structures, this one also so- cialized its members, which, in the case of the Chileans on the gold roll, meant "metropolitanization." Thus, when nationalization, with its threat to their standards of con- sumption, came in 1971, many gold roll Chilean employees left along with their U.S. counterparts (Gall, l972:7; Reynolds, 1965:390-391). . The multinationals' vertical integration which locates successive stages of production in different nation-states makes possible a third mechanism of surplus appropriation, the allocation of costs, tax burdens, and profits in a man- ner which maximizes the total returns to the multinational. International transactions that were measured at the points of exit and entry to the national economy in the days when national firms were the dominant organizational form, are now intra-firm and thus measured only by the information provided by the accounting departments of the multinational corporations. Within this system, transfer pricing can con- centrate profits in the processing stage and the nation with the most favorable tax structure; operations at an early 252 stage of processing that are marginal or even losing propo- sitions in and of themselves can produce a profit for the multinational as a result of control over a later stage of processing. The shifting of costs, taxes, and profits af- fects not only the interests of the hinterland nations. The U.S. allows corporations to claim as tax credit against U.S. taxes on foreign earned income any taxes "paid or deemed paid" to foreign governments and grants generous depletion allowances to extractive industries. As a result, U.S. mining multinationals paid no taxes to the U.S. government on the $1.3 and $1.2 billion they remitted from foreign earnings in 1968 and 1970 respectively (Multinational Cor- poration and the World Economy, 1973:17). This is likely to be a continuing pattern since hinterland nations that "possess" mineral and petroleum resources worked by multi— nationals are making increased efforts to link the export economy based on-these resources to the national political economy through taxation. This is a defensive form of na- tional integration, but probably the only path open to them short of nationalization. Again illustrative material provides the best evidence of this loss of surplus to Chile, although access to corpor- ate accounts would make possible some efforts at measure- ment. Both Anaconda and Kennecott supported their sales operations in Western EurOpe and Japan in part by overhead charges on their Chilean subsidiaries (NACLA, 1972:112). Presumably this was because a substantial portion of Chilean 253 copper was sold in these nations during recent years. It might be argued that under Chilean ownership there would also be selling costs, and this is undoubtedly true. How- ever, there would be no need to support the competing mar- keting organizations of both Anaconda and Kennecott as was the case prior to 1971. The organization of Chilean copper through the two U.S. based multinationals also produced duplication and surplus loss at earlier processing stages. Smelting and refining operations require 100,000 tons of COpper per year to maximize economies of scale although smaller operations are sometimes undertaken. Since the Pot- rerillos/El Salvador complex seldom reached that level of output, until the mid 1960's most of Andes copper output was exported prior to the refining stage on "freighters bring[ing] machinery, timber, cement, equipment, and consumer goods and carryIing] away bars of blister COpper for refining at Perth Amboy, New Jersey" (Pedersonz236). Similarly, for many years, the output from the small and medium sized mines was exported as ores and concentrates because the low production levels of each mine meant that none could support a smelter or refinery. Nor did they have reliable access to the smel- ters and refineries of the Gran Mineria. In the early 1950's, the Chilean government built a smelting and refining complex at Las Venturas in an effort to capture some portion of the surplus loss to Chile from this pattern (UNIDO, 1969:47-48; United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:88). Even the, the new complex was smaller than was economically desirable 254 because of the low total output of the mines outside of the Gran Mineria. Had the Chilean copper industry been inte- grated in terms of the Chilean national political economy, the multiplication of smelting and refining facilities with- in the Gran Mineria on the one hand, and the lack of access of small producers to these facilities on the other, could have been avoided. The problem of maximizing economies of scale at the refinery level is particularly important since it is at this and later stages that most profits are made and can be made even with high cost mines such as the smaller Chilean mines (Fortune, January 1955:93-94). The very nature of COpper deposits also puts the com- panies in a position to apprOpriate part of the Chilean sur- plus through shifts in costs and profits. In most cases, other minerals are found with COpper in porphyry deposits. (In fact, some of the major Canadian COpper mines actually produce as much lead or zinc as copper.) Gold, silver and molybdenum are particularly common with 25-35 percent of U.S. production of each of these metals coming from copper mines. As an example, Kennecott's Bingham Canyon mine is the second largest producer of gold in the Western Hemi- sphere. The mines of the Gran Mineria in Chile also contain substantial amounts of these metals, accounting for all of Chilean molybdenum output, one-third of the gold output and three-fourths of silver output. Because of chemical bonding, these metals are not separated until the electrolytic re- fining stage and thus, in exports of blister copper, their 255 value for tax purposes must be estimated. This enables the companies to circumvent the regulatory efforts of the Chilean state while at the same time apprOpriating a portion of the Chilean surplus. This is particularly true for Braden Copper Company which has always exported most of its output in fire refined form, much of which is later elec- trolytically refined on a toll basis by ASARCO, a closely linked company since the days of the Guggenheims. As a hypothetical example of the amounts involved, one ounce of gold recovered from a ton of 99 percent blister copper selling at 35¢ per pound (a high price until the late 1960's) would increase the revenues from that ton by over 5 percent. Since all three companies export some blister COpper, and at times in the past even some ores and concentrates, this is probably a significant loss of Chilean surplus. The re- covery of precious metals at metropole refiners also re— duces the cost per pound of U.S. COpper mining, making it more competitive with output from other areas. In addition, the combining of blister COpper from different sources en- ables U.S. refineries to achieve an Optimum mix which lowers the cost per unit. Since the cost per pound of COpper in the United States is greater than any other major producer, these benefits from the geographical and vertical integra— tion of the multinationals are significant in terms of ad— ditional profits. Thus, the appropriation of Chilean sur- plus feeds the growth of metrOpolitan industry (Brudenius, 1969:191-192; McMahon, 1965:3-4; OECD, 1969:85-86; Wideman, 1965:277-279). 256 The final mechanism of actual surplus appropriation is largely the result of the mineral extractive nature of the multinationals in Chile. This mechanism has usually been analyzed as the enclave effect (Levin, 1960). Most of the loss of surplus that results from the enclave structure of the Gran Mineria falls under the heading of potential sur— plus, particularly the failure to establish forward and backward linkages between COpper and the remainder of the Chilean economy. HOwever, the question in the Gran Mineria can fruitfully be analyzed as an appropriation of actual surplus by the mining multinationals. The issue of the benefits to Chile through wage and salary payments by the large copper companies is a complex one: On the one hand, the wage rate is considerably above the national average, yet at the same time the number of employees has remained fairly constant for several decades. The Gran Mineria-has become increasingly capital-intensive and input-saving in general. Perhaps the best way to ap- proach the issue and to understand the enclave aspect of Chilean copper is by considering the geographical situation of the COpper towns and the multifaceted activities of the copper companies. For example, the E1 Teniente mine area covers300 square miles at altitudes between 8 and 10 thou- sand feet, and since it is located in an otherwise infer— tile region, is fairly isolated from any other population centers. Braden (Kennecott) built and Operated a railroad which moved the ore from Sewell (the mining town) to 257 Caletones for concentration and smelting in company-owned plants. The town of Sewell was built from scratch by Braden, and, as at Chiquicamata, a somewhat less isolated area, much of the food and consumer goods were imported on the multi» national's ships and delivered to the towns via their rail- roads and trucks. Nor is this pattern, which strongly re- sembles the earlier nitrate towns, a thing of the past. In the 1960's, the Chile Exploration Company described its activities as the mining, smelting and refining of ore; the Operation Of power plants, water and telephone systems, railroads, foundaries, and warehouses; and the ownership of houses, hospitals, schools, stores, bakeries, clubs and "other service facilities for employees" (Moody's Industrigi Manual, 1966:1014). Andes Copper Company carried out simi« lar activities and, in a parallel to United Fruit's Puerto Barrios in Guatemala, owns and Operates the port of Barquito (Davis, 1924:85-90; Gall, 1972:2—4, United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:89-90). Within this setting, it may be useful to look at the miners and their families in much the same way that theorists of internal colonialism are beginning to examine the ghetto, and particularly the welfare recipients within the ghettc. To a large extent, it appears that the inhabitants of the company mining towns may simply serve as conduits for the copper companies. The relatively high wages (by Chilean standards) paid to both the miners and supervisory personnel are largely returned as income to company stores, housing 258 agencies, and utilities. Thus the insulation of the mining towns from the rest of the Chilean political economy gives the high wages a very limited multiplier effect, further supporting the argument that government taxation is the major link between the mineral producing multinationals and the national economy (Girvan, 1970:517-518; Rollins, 1970: 189-193). Instead, the potential multiplier effect is transferred via the geographical integration of the multi- nationals and stimulates the production Of manufactured goods in the metropole. The enclave structure of the Gran Mineria also alters the Chilean class structure. Through the relatively high wages and the importation of metrOpolitan consumer goods to the mining towns, the multinationals create what might be called a labor aristocracy (Sunkel, 1965:129) with an ori~ entation towards the metrOpolis. In this case, the inter- national demonstration effect is transferred via the geo- graphical integration of the multinational and penetrates the hinterland through a portion of the working class (Pinto, 1965:45-46). This economic fragmentation of the Chilean class structure as a result of the international mechanisms Of surplus appropriation has its political re~ flection. While COpper miners, as is almost universally true for mining areas, have a long tradition of radicalism and were important in the successful early emergence of the Chilean left, there are some interesting differences between voting patterns in COpper towns and other mining 259 towns. The contrast is particularly marked in the case of coal miners who work in Chilean-owned mines and are not tied to the international class structure which shapes the lives of the COpper miners. Thus, while the latter gave Allende over 40 percent of their vote in 1970, more than 10 percent above the national average, the coal mining towns voted over 75 percent for the U.P., double the national average. This pattern has existed for several decades as Petras and Zeitlin‘s analysis of earlier elections demon- strates (1968:238). In sum, the political economy of international copper creates a strata which is both a labor aristocracy within the hinterland and, at the same time, is linked, through the mechanisms of appropriation of actual economic surplus by the copper multinationals, to the metropole. Once again, the amount involved is difficult to calculate, but some orders of magnitude can be suggested. The COpper Gran Mineria employs between one-fifth and one-fourth of the labor force in mining and quarrying and probably accounts for at least one-third of the wages, salaries and income of business enterprises in this sector. In recent years, around 9 percent of the national income has gone to mining which would indicate about 3 percent to the Gran Mineria. While further calculations become increasingly speculative at this point, if as much as 1 percent of the national in- come is lost through the enclave structure of the Gran Mineria, this would amount to about 20 percent of the average 260 Chilean savings rate during the 1960's and increase the pro- portion of surplus appropriated to total savings in Table 10 accordingly. I To conclude this section, when the amounts involved in the four mechanisms of surplus appropriation are added, a conservative estimate Of the results suggests that there would be an increase of at least a half in the amount of savings available for net investment during the 1950's and 1960's. Since many of the linkages which retain part of the actual surplus in Chile have been established since World War II, the loss was probably greater during previous years. Whatever the exact percentages involved, the loss of actual surplus only scratches the surface. As I shall try to make clear, although only in outline form, it is through the loss of potential economic surplus that Chile has suffered the most extensive damage and through the con- trol over this potential economic surplus that the multi- national mining corporations have realized the biggest gains. CHAPTER 8 THE LOSS OF POTENTIAL ECONOMIC SURPLUS When I speak of the Pacific Rim, I am putting the broadest possible construction on the term-- the western coasts of South America, Central Amer- ica, and our own continent, and extending beyond Australia and the Far East to India. There is no more vast or rich area for resource deve10pment or trade growth in the world today than this im- mense region and it is virtually our own front yard...I emphasize that this is a largely under- developed area, yet an area rich in an immense variety of resources and potential capabilities. --Rudolph A. Peterson President of Bank of America, 1968 The mechanisms Of appropriation and control over the potential economic surplus--that amount beyond essential consumption which an economy could produce with its natural and technological environment and its employable productive resources--are rooted in the political economy of inter- national COpper organized by the multinational corporation. Here I will discuss the two most substantial losses of po— tential economic surplus: (l) the increasing gap between Chile's proportion of capitalist world COpper reserves and her proportion of capitalist world output since World War II; and (2) the locational decisions by the multinationals over the distribution of the facilities which are necessary for the processing and fabricating of copper and the re- sulting employment and profit flows. This second mechanism 261 262 of potential surplus loss also touches on the question of linkages between COpper and the larger political economy in the metropole and hinterland. What follows is only a sketch of the research I have undertaken on these questions. Here as elsewhere, my analysis is limited to the production and marketing within the capitalist world since this has been the limits of Chile's markets and the multinationals' Operations through 1970. While the proved and probable reserves and the actual copper production of the major producing regions in the cap- italist world have all increased since World War II, there has been no major development of new COpper deposits since the rise of the African copper belt in the 1920's. Nor, as thoroughly as the multinationals have prospected "the three of the four quarters of the globe where exploration is pos- sible" (Kennecott Copper Corporation, l951:7), is such a discovery likely-in the foreseeable future. Thus, over 80 percent of capitalist world reserves have remained concen- trated in just six nations: Chile, Peru, U.S., Canada, Zambia, and Zaire. The five nations which led the capital- ist world in copper output in 1970 also did so throughout the 1930's, 1940's, 1950's, and 1960's. Peru is the only newcomer to the top six nations during this period, but the Peruvian deposits were also known much earlier (Herfindahl, 1959:159; Wideman, 1965:286-287; Copper, 1970 Annual Sta- tistical Supplement). This geographical concentration is reflected in the corporate concentration of COpper production. _Prior to 263 the 1970's, ten multinational mining corporations based in four countries own over 70 percent of the capitalist world reserves: Anaconda, Kennecott, ASARCO, Newmont Mining (U.S.); Noranda, International Nickel (Canada); Anglo Amer- ican Corporation, Phodesian Selection Trust (Britain); and the Belgium firm which was the COpper industry in Zaire through 1970, the Union Miniere du Haut Katanga. Pre-l970 Anaconda, estimated to own more than 30 percent of these reserves, was the giant among giants (O'Hanlon, 1966:117; Hardy, 1969:35). As Anaconda was the richest corporation, so Chile had the richest copper resources. Throughout the last quarter of a century, over 20 percent of world COpper reserves and more than a quarter of capitalist world reserves have been located in Chile. This cornucopian abundance of COpper deposits comes in a form which makes United States domestic mine owners green with envy. Chilean ore content runs be- tween l.5 percent and 2.25 percent, double the less than 1 percent average for the U.S. and higher than Canada's l to 1.5 percent or Peru's 1-2 percent (McMahon, 1965:55-63). Only the African COpper belt, with several mines of 2.5 percent or more cOpper, has an overall ore content greater than Chile's; however, the lack of adequate transportation facilities raises the price of African copper. While Chile's mines are all located within 100 miles of the coast and linked to Chilean ports by railroads, the major African mines are more than 1,000 miles from ports, a 264 journey which involved both rail and river transport until the mid 1960's. In sum, industry studies show Chile as having one of the lowest costs per pound of COpper produced, considerably below that of the U.S. mines of Anaconda or Kennecott and easily competitive with the African COpper mines (Griffin, 1969:129; O'Hanlon, 1966:121; "Mining in Latin Americaf'l969z85-86). Despite these advantages, Chile's share of capitalist world output has not matched her proportion of reserves at any time since World War II. Supplying about 18 percent of capitalist world copper production in the late 1940's, Chile's share has steadily declined falling to only 13 per~ cent by 1970 and averaging 15 percent for the entire quarter century. In fact, during the 1944-1954 period, Chile's output fell over 25 percent in absolute terms and the 1944 peak was not surpassed until 1959. Since the foreign-owned Gran Mineria accounted for over 90 percent of Chilean cop- per production through 1960, and at least 79 percent during the next decade, the failure Of Chile to realize her poten- tial output lies in the failure of the multinationals to expand production in Chile as rapidly as capitalist world production increased (COpper, relevant issues; Griffin, 1969: 125-135; United States, Bureau of Mines, relevant issues). Thus, had Chilean copper production matched her share of capitalist world COpper reserves and the returns to Chile per pound of copper produced remained constant, the amount of surplus accruing to Chile from the Gran Mineria would 265 have been greater by 65-70 percent. Once in power, it was, Of course, difficult for the Unidad Popular government to rapidly increase Chile's share, since the U.S. market, al- most one-third of the total, was eliminated. Further, and most importantly, any gains on the part of Chile would probably have meant losses, not to the U.S. as the leading producer, but to other hinterland nations. This latter situation was structured into Frei's Chileanization program, drawn up in a manner which gave Chile less than 40 percent of the benefits at the prevailing prices and more than 50 percent of the benefits from price increases. Thus, Chile would have gained from political or economic instability in Zambia, Zaire, or Peru (Griffin, 1969:163). What were the gains to the U.S. multinationals from this loss of potential Chilean surplus? Their most impor- tant benefits were: (1) the ability to keep some portion of their COpper production capacity in areas of proven po- litical stability; (2) the accumulation of capital for di- versification into other raw materials including a competing metal, aluminum; and (3) political leverage in bargaining with the Chilean government. To briefly elaborate: (l) the majority Of Kennecott's production of copper comes from U.S. mines, several Of which would be quite marginal and perhaps losing propositions if the price of COpper were to fall to the level which "free competition" would dictate. While Anaconda was dependent on Chile for two-thirds of its COpper production, their largest U.S. mine at Butte, 266 Montana would also be a marginal producer in direct competi- tion with other areas of the world (Griffin, 1969:127-128; Mikesall, l97la:370). (2) While Anaconda and Kennecott have long been vertically integrated and thus supplied much of their own fuel, transportation, and chemicals used in pro— cessing, each diversified industrially during the post World War II period. By 1970, they were less dependent than Chile on COpper, a development financed in part by Chilean earn- ings. Anaconda has'emerged as the fourth largest producer of aluminum in the U.S., a metal which has displaced copper in several areas including high voltage overhead lines. Anaconda's joint venture with Reynolds and Kaiser in Jamai- can aluminum provides a classic example, with a cross elas- ticity twist, of the competition between hinterland nations within the framework of the multinational corporation. Kennecott's efforts at diversification have included (a) the acquisition of a_substantial interest in Kaiser Aluminum; (b) a controlling interest in a Nigerian tin venture; (c) investments,later liquidated, in South African gold mines; and (d) a controlling interest in a joint venture with New Jersey Zinc in a Canadian iron-titanium deposit, the largest in the world. In 1968, Kennecott capped their diversifica- tion efforts with the purchase of Peabody Coal Company, a major factor in the U.S. coal industry with 10-15 percent of the total output. Once a strip miner, always a strip miner (Copper, relevant issues; Moody's Industrials 1956, 1961, 1966, and 1971; OECD, 1969:58; company reports); (3) 267 the Chilean government has repeatedly attempted to expand the Chilean share of the capitalist world COpper market, sometimes through marketing controls and sometimes through incentives to the companies. The companies have equally repeatedly responded by demanding tax concessions and legal guarantees and have expanded output only when these were provided. Twice during the 1950's the multinationals in- creased their investment in marginal U.S. mines after con- sidering and rejecting the Option of increased output from their Chilean properties. Even during the Chileanization period, the companies refused to increase their output de- spite the agreements with the government. Thus, over 90 percent of the increase in Chilean production in 1966-1970 came from the small and medium mines not part of the Gran Mineria. Evidently the companies were awaiting the outcome Of the 1970 elections (ECLA, 1969 and 1971; Griffin, 1969: 155-163; Mikesall, 1971a). The second mechanism of potential surplus appropriation is rooted in the international vertical integration of the copper multinationals. This integration gives them consid- erable choice in their locational decisions concerning the facilities for the processing of COpper. The result, as Galtung (1970:85, 87) suggests, is a vertical interaction Irelation, "interaction between metrOpole and hinterland across processing levels." That is to say that it cannot be stressed enough that Anaconda and Kennecott did not just mine Chilean COpper--they also milled Chilean COpper, smelted 268 Chilean COpper, refined Chilean COpper, fabricated Chilean copper, and sold Chilean copper--but not always or even pri- marily in Chile. Nor was Chile their only source of COpper. Kennecott owns four of the dozen most productive mines in the U.S. and Anaconda another two. Anaconda also has an- other source Of foreign COpper, Greene Cananea, a Mexican mine whose output is similar to that of the old Potrerillos property. Once again, raw material producing regions and nations compete with each other through the framework of the multinational corporation. For a grasp of the flows of raw materials and output determination instructions which are created by the vertical integration of the multinationals, Girvan's model of the division between administrative and Operational functions in the mineral extracting multinational is suggestive (Girvan, 1970:409-504). It needs to be modified to fit the specificity of copper processing, however, While, as noted previously, COpper passes through several stages of pro- cessing, it is only economical to transport copper long distances between the smelting and refining stages and be— tween the refining and fabricating states. (In the past, however, and at times even today, large volumes of COpper may be transported between the concentrating and the smelting stages.) This is because, by weight, the ore is only 1-3 percent COpper while the matte (COpper after it is concen- trated) is 25-50 percent copper. However, after smelting, the blister is 99 percent COpper. The technological 269 imperatives of copper processing placed in the organization- al shell of the multinational corporation means that the flow of material for processing is not determined solely by ”market" considerations, nor by what would be least costly and most beneficial to national political economies. In- stead, it is the economic and political priorities of the multinational-—what areas are politically secure, where does an investment stake already exist, where are the most prof— itable markets--that are decisive. Figure 2 depicts the structure that emerges. The results of these decisions for the political eco- nomy of Chilean copper are summarized in the statistics of Table 11 (page 271). The most striking fact about the figures in the table is the decline, beginning in the early 1950's, in both the proportion and the absolute amount of copper exported in refined form. Throughout the whole per- iod covered, the-proportion refined was never as great as during the 1926-1933 period and in the year 1953-1962 and 1964-1965, the absolute amount refined was less than the pre-depression peak year of 1929. The fall in refined ex- ports also took place during the same years that the Chilean government constructed a smelter and refinery to handle the output Of the small and medium sized mines. Thus, the de- cline of refined exports from the Gran Mineria must have been even greater than the overall figures suggest. Through- out these years, the U.S. continued to be the leading pro- ducer of refined copper in the capitalist world with about METROPOLE MARKET 270 METROPOLE MARKET f _ Owned Refiner - //’ fiurzumn/ . / ® Owned Production Facility "' Refinery Capacity 50% of Smelted Oil/l, ‘\ \ METROPOLE ‘\~~ MARKET .. I O Owned Mine ' Smelter & Corporation® . Refinery Central Headquarters I / . // ® Owned ' ’//’ Refinery ' HINTERLAND Facility ED Owned Production Refinery Capacity K\\\f5% of Smelted O::/// Flow of Instructions -- -—— -—’ Flow of Unrefined Ore —- - ——’ Flow of Refined Ore D: Figure 2: Hypothetical Structure of a Copper Multinational 271 .vuhH 0cm muhH ummmoo can “mm .02 .mmuoz OHEocoom mHch .ommou Eoum OmumHnonw "oanlmmmH MOM mIH .mHoo .an . .mmmH .mOHumfid sHumH mo mm>unm OHeocoom .usm OHEonoom .dqum Eouw pmumHsonu "mmmHumva MOM muH .mHou "mmousom h.m> m.ovm m.mo o.Hve o.nm v.0nm m.>mm oan H.mn m.mmm m.mw N.mmv q.mm m.>mm m.amm ame m.m~ n.aHm m.mm m.nnm m.mm m.nmo N.mmo mmmH m.Hm «.mmm m.nm m.Hom n.mm m.Hmw m.ooo nmmH N.vm m.mmm v.vm H.5Hm m.Hm m.mmm m.nmw mweH «.mm m.hmv m.Hv m.on m.mm h.mHm m.mmm mmmH m.vm m.nmm m.mm N.MHN o.mm o.nmm m.mmm vme ¢.vm ¢.nmm H.mv m.mv~ m.nm w.vmm H.How mmmH H.5m N.OHm >.Nv m.ovm w.om w.mom h.mmm mmmH h.mm H.Hmv o.ov m.OHm ~.mm m.va m.mvm HomH H.om N.mnv m.Hv H.mHm «.mm m.NHm m.Hmm oomH m.Hm m.mmv m.mv m.mHm m.mm N.vom m.vvm mmmH m.om «.mHv H.mm H.mmH m.mm m.mmv «.mov mmmH N.om m.mmv m.mv v.ch o.mm m.nnv m.vmv nmmH m.om m.vvv m.nv m.MHm m.Hm m.nev h.amw mmmH m.om o.vmm m.om v.OH~ v.mm v.MH¢ m.mmv mmmH m.mm H.mmm m.Hm H.mmH m.m0H >.mnm o.mmm vmmH >.mm m.mmm n.Hm v.moH H.mm 0.0mm m.mmm mmmH h.Hm m.vnm o.v> v.cmm n.mm m.mnm o.mov mmmH m.vm o.Hmm m.vn v.ovm m.om v.mmm >.omm HmmH m.mm m.mvm w.mn m.m¢m m.mm m.amm m.mom ommH h.vm m.Hmm o.Hn h.mmm m.coH ~.vhm N.Hnm mva h.mm m.m~v o.mo ~.mam n.5m >.vmv H.mvv mva Hmuoe mo m .uEd mOHOQXm mo w .uEd coHuonpoum mo w Omuuoaxm OOOSOOHO new» mHumst cmuo muuomxw pmcwam Omuuoaxm memoo Hmmaoo mo sOHuoncoum Amcou OHuumE ooo CH muCSOEm HHOV osmHumva "Monaco :mmHH20 .HH mHnt 272 one-third of the total while mining about one-fourth of the copper in the capitalist world. Chile was the leading sup- plier of unrefined imports to the U.S., providing over a third of the total during the 1948-1970 years. Further, despite consumption in excess of mine production throughout these years, the U.S. remained one of the leading exporters of refined COpper. By the 1960's, as Brazil and Argentina became two of the five largest customers for the U.S. re- fined exports, Chilean copper was reaching these Latin Amer- ican nations via U.S. East Coast refineries. Even more incredible, throughout the 1950's, COpper wire and cable was eXported to Chile from U.S. fabricating plants! (COpper, selected issues; Skelton, 1937:401 and 405; and sources cited in Table 11). t It was the decisions of the copper multinationals, Anaconda and Kennecott, which shaped this structure of Chile's international copper trade. During Chile's peak copper producing years of World War II, when the price of copper was frozen in the U.S. at 12¢ per pound, the com- panies refined as much as 85 percent of their Chilean out- put in Chile. However, when the Chilean government attempted to assert control over the COpper industry in the early 1950's, through increased control over marketing, higher rates of taxation, and exchange rates designed to maximize the returns to Chile, the companies shifted more of the re- fining to their U.S. facilities. In 1953, the Chilean gov- ernment tried to establish a price for refined copper 3¢/1b. 273 above the 24.5¢/lb. set by the U.S. government during the Korean War. In that same year, the prOportion of Chilean exports in refined form fell from 74 percent to 52 percent. This drop in refined exports was also reflected in U.S. import statistics. Refined imports from Chile fell from 85 percent of the U.S. total in 1952 to 54 percent in 1953 while Chile's share of U.S. pprefined imports rose from 25 percent to 34 percent in these two years. (In fact, Chile even lost ground in capitalist world smelter production, going from over 20 percent of the total in 1946 to only 14 percent in 1955 and 12 percent in 1970.) Interestingly enough, the decline in refined production in Chile occurred despite the existence of over 500,000 MT/Y refinery capacity in the Gran Mineria by the 1950's. Although by the end of that decade these refineries were evidently operating at no more than 50 percent of capacity, Kennecott completed a 198,000 ton electrolytic refinery at Baltimore, Maryland in 1959. Much of the ore which went to this refinery came from El Teniente. Anaconda expanded and modernized their Perth Amboy refinery during this same period. While the U.S. tariff on unrefined COpper was not in effect between 1947-1963, during 1932-1947 and 1963-1966 when the tariff was in effect, ores, concentrates, scrap and blister copper were not dutiable when they were imported for smelting and/ or refining and re-export. Even with the tariff, the cost per pound of Chilean COpper evidently made it profitable for import, refining and consumption (Bidwell, 1958:103, 108; Copper, relevant issues; Company reports). 274 The failure of Braden Copper Company to expand refined production from E1 Teniente provides a particularly instruc- tive example of the determination of hinterland political economy by the multinational political economy. Until the early 1950's, Kennecott did not even own an electrolytic refinery in the U.S. although it did have a fabricating sub- sidiary. Kennecott's mine and smelter production was re- fined on a toll basis by ASARCO (formerly American Smelting and Refining Company) to which Kennecott had been linked by stockholdings and directors since the days of the Guggenheim Exploration Company. Thus, Braden also owned no electro- lytic refining facilities and much of Braden's blister and fire refined copper1 went to ASARCO's Baltimore and Perth Amboy refineries for further processing. The loss of po- tential Chilean surplus was converted into a profitable metrOpolitan relationship (Kennecott COpper Corporation, relevant years).- The total loss to Chile from this structure of inter- national COpper is difficult to determine with any precision but some rough indicators are available. First, refining Of Chilean copper in the U.S. certainly entailed an export of jobs to the U.S. Total U.S. employment in mining and quarrying of copper is divided approximately 50 percent in mining, 16.7 percent in smelting, and 33.3 percent in re- fining. The latter percentage has tended to rise slightly during the post World War II years, reflecting both in- creased productivity in mining and continued imports of 275 unrefined ore from hinterland nations (Copper, Spring 1957: 14; McMahon, 1965:299-201; Wideman, 1965:292). Since Chile refined an average of only 54 percent of her COpper exports in the years 1948-1970, employment in COpper refining could have been nearly doubled if refining had taken place in Chile. This would have provided more jobs, a higher level of average income and greatly increased the multiplier effect of copper wages since the refineries were located in less isolated towns where the enclave structure of the Gran Mineria was not as limiting. Other indicators of the loss to Chile are more indeterminate. If refinery production had remained at even the 1948 level, of 300,000 MT/Y (an output not reached again until 1966), the pressure for the realization of potential forward and backward linkages with the rest of the Chilean economy might have been greater. For example, it was not until the Chileanization program of the 1960's that the copper companies agreed to increase their use of Chilean coal as an energy source. In the in- terim, Chile continued to give up vital foreign exchange for the import of petroleum for use in the Gran Mineria, despite an increase in Chilean petroleum output of over 2,000 percent between 1950 and 1969 (United States, Dept. of Commerce, 1960:188; Griffin, 1969:154-155). There is one facet of copper processing that Table 11 says nothing about. To have use value, copper must go be— yond the refined stage and be fabricated into the shapes, sizes, and dimensions needed by other industries. It is 276 the fabrication of COpper and the sales of fabricators to the electrical, automobile, and aerospace industries that provides the linkages which are important spin offs of the copper industry and are the basis of much of its potential in the process of economic growth (OECD, 1969:17; UNIDO, 1972:20-25). The multinational COpper corporations have never produced any fabricated COpper in Chile despite the fact that each is integrated through the fabricating stage and is a major factOr in the U.S. fabricating industry. Technological difficulties are not the issue since fabrica— tion is considered relatively simple in terms of the tech— nological SOphistication required. In addition, experience in the fabrication of one non-ferrous metal is readily gen- eralizable to others (Richter, l927a:7l4). Even under the Chileanization program of the 1960's, the best that could be done was to get a commitment from Anaconda to "consider" the possibility of establishing a fabricating plant for export. The Chilean government did make one past effort at developing its own fabricating products for export. Limited success was achieved for a few years during the early 1960's when there was a general shortage of COpper in the capitalist world, but Chile was unable to compete with the vertically integrated multinationals and the tariff barriers to metro- pole markets. By the end of the 1960's, semi-fabricated copper exports had fallen to less than 2 percent of the total copper exports (UNIDO, 1969:74; UNIDO, 1972:125). (Under the Unidad POpular, Chile reached an agreement with 277 Romania to develop a fabricating industry which would market much of its output in the socialist nations.) The loss to Chile through the refusal of the multina- tionals to develop a fabricating industry in Chile has been immense. Without including the question of spin offs from such an industry, the following statistics suggest the di- mensions of the loss: The 1947, 1956, and 1967 U.S. Census of Manufacturing and Mineral Industries report employment in copper rolling and drawing establishments alone to be double that in the mining of COpper, six times the employ- ment in the smelting of COpper and three times the employ- ment in copper refining. Employment in wire and cable mills and brOnze and brass mills was again greater than employment in mining and smelting. Value added in the stages of pro- cessing beyond copper refining was more than three times that in mining, smelting, and refining. In this area alone, then, the contribution of the Gran Mineria to Chilean devel- opment was less than half of what it could have been. In I sum, for Chile as for most of the remainder of the third world, the most enduring legacy of the capitalist metropoles has been the loss of potential economic surplus, a potential which has been absorbed in the development of those metro- poles. 278 NOTES 1 Fire refined copper is acceptable for some industrial uses. While over 99 percent COpper by weight, it is not as pure as electrolytic COpper and sells at a slight discount. Electrolytic refining is necessary to recover precious metals such as gold and silver, however. All COpper used in the electrical industry which accounts for 50 percent of the total market is electrolytic COpper. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Ackerman, Frank and Arthur Mac MacEwan 1972 "Inflation, Recession and Crisis, Or, Would You Buy a New Car From This Man." Review of Radical Political Economics 4 (August): 4-37. Ageton, Robert W. and Gertrude N. Greenspoon 1970 "Copper." in Mineral Facts and Problems, Bureau of Mines Bulletin 650. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Allen, Frederick Lewis 1964 Only Yesterday. New York: Harper and Row. Allende, Salvador 1970- "Chile: The First Battle." Tricontinental 21-22 1971 (November-February): 3-14. - Amunategui, Gregorio 1968 "The Role of Copper in the Chilean Economy." in Claudio Veliz (ed.), Latin America and the Carib- bean: A Handbook. London: Oxford University Press. Anaconda Company- Annual Report. 1944-1973, selected years. Baklanoff, Eric N. 1966 "International Taxation and Mineral Development: The Political Economy of Chile's La Gran Mineria de Cobre." Pp. 323-341 in Proceedings of the 58th Annual Conference of National Tax Associa- tion. Harrisberg, Pa.: National Tax Association Balbus, Isaac 1971 "Ruling Elite Theory vs. Marxist Class Analysis." Monthly Review 23 (May): 36-46. Baran, Paul ' 1957 The Political Economy of Growth. New York: Monthly Review Press. Baran, Paul 1969 "Economic Progress and Economic Surplus." in John O'Neill (ed.), The Longer View: Essays Towards a Critique of Political Economy. New York: Monthly Review Press. 279 280 Baran, Paul and Paul Sweezy 1966 Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Social and Economic Order. New York: Monthly Review Press. Barclay, William and Mitchell Stengel 1975 "Surplus and Surplus Value." Review of Radical Political Economics (forthcoming). Barnet, Richard J. 1973 Roots Of War. Baltimore: Penguin. Barraclough, Geoffrey 1975 "The Great World Crisis I." The New York Review of Books 21 (January 23); 20-29. Beckford, George L.‘ 1972 Persistent Poverty: UnderdevelOpment in Planta- tion Economies of the Third World. New York: Oxford University Press. Bell, Daniel 1973 The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. New York: Basic Books. Bernstein, Barton J. . 1969 "The New Deal: The Conservative Achievements of Liberal Reform." in Barton J. Bernstein (ed.), Towards a New Past: Dissenting Essays in American History. New York: Vintage. Bidwell, Percy W. 1958 Raw Materials: A Study of American Policy. New YOrk: Harper and Brothers. Blackburn, Robin (ed.) 1973 Ideology in Social Science: Readings in Critical Social Theory. New York: Vintage Books. Blaug, Marc 1968 Economic Theory in Retrospect. Homewood, 111.: R. D. IrWin. Bluestone, Barry 1972a "Capitalism and Poverty in America: A Discussion." Monthly Review 24 (June): 65-71. Bluestone, Barry 1972b "Economic Crises and the Law of Uneven DevelOp- ment." Politics and Society (Fall): 65-82. Bodenheimer, Susanne 1971 ”Dependency and Imperialism: The Roots of Latin American Development." in K. T. Fann (ed.), Read- ings in U.S. Imperialism. Boston: Porter Sargent. 281 Bodenheimer, Susanne 1969 "Stagnation in Liberty: The Frei Experiment in Chile." NACLA Newsletter 2 & 3 (February & March): 1-9 8 1-10. Brown, Martin S. and John Butler 1968 The Production, Marketing and Consumption of Cop- per and Aluminum. New York: Praeger. Brundenius , Claes 1972 "The Anatomy of Imperialism: The Case of the Mul- tinational Mining Corporations in Peru." Journal of Peace Research 2: 189-207. Burgess, C. H. £1973 Statement before the Subcommittee on Minerals, Materials, and Fuels of the Committee on Interior and Insular Affairs of the U.S. Senate, 93rd Congress, in Mineral Resources of the Seabed. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. 13111rns, E. Bradford 11973 "Reform Gunned Down: True Verdict on Allende." Nation 217 (October 29): 426-429. Bt1£3iness Week 21968 "Chile and COpper." (December 7): 10-12. CZXILA 21973 CALA Newsletter (December). Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. 1969 Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Chandler, Alfred D. and Fritz Redlich 1961 "Recent Developments in American Business Admin- istration and Their Conceptualization." Business History Review (Spring): 103-128. CheI‘ry, Robert 1973' "Class Struggle and the Nature of the Working Class." The Review of Radical Political Economics 512 (Summer): 47-86. Childe, Gordon 1954 What Happened in History. Baltimore: Penguin. Canper Copper: Quarterly Industry Report. 1954-1971. CORE-o Chile Economic Notes. 1970-1973. 282 Cox, Oliver C. 1959 Foundations of Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press. Dalton , George 1960 "A Note of Clarification on Economic Surplus.“ American Anthropologist 63 (June): 483-490. Dalton , George .1963 "Economic Surplus, Once Again." American Anthro- pologist 65 (April): 389-394. Davis , Watson 11924 The Story of COpper. New York: Century Publishers. Dobb , Maurice IL963 Studies in the DevelOpment of Capitalism. New York: International Publishers. Dc>ss Santos, Theotonio IL971 "The Structure of Dependence." in K. T. Fann (ed.), Readings in U.S. Imperialism. Boston: Porter Sargent. Dowd, Douglas F. 1.974 The Twisted Dream: Capitalist DevelOpment in the United States Since 1776. Cambridge: Winthrop Publishers. ' EK213A 1.951 Economic Survey of Latin America, 1949. New York: United Nations. IRZIJA " 1965 Economic Survey of Latin America, 1964. New York: United Nations. ECIJA. 1966a Economic DevelOpment of Latin America in the Post War Period. New York: United Nations. ECLA 1966b Economic Survey of Latin America, 1965. New York: United Nations. ECLA 15366c The Process of Industrial DevelOpment in Latin America. New York: United Nations. ECIJ; 1967 Economic Survey of Latin America, 1966. New York: United Nations. ECIJK 31970 Economic Survey of Latin America, 1969. New York: United Nations. 283 ECLA 1972 Economic Survey of Latin America, 1971. New York: United Nations. :Economic Report of the President 1972 Economic Report of the President. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Economic Report of the President 1973 Economic Report of the President. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Ekiwards, Richard C., Michael Reich, and Thomas E. Weisskopf (eds.) 1972 The Capitalist System: A Radical Analysis of American Society. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall. Edwards , Thomas L . 1972 Economic DevelOpment and Reform in Chile: Prog- ress Under Frei, 1964-1970. Monograph No. 8. East Lansing, Mich.: Latin American Studies Center, Michigan State University. Engineering and Mining Journal Engineering and Mining Journal. 1930-1973; Engler, Robert .1961 The Politics of Oil. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. FQKC) $1962 The State of Food and Agriculture, 1962. Rome: Uhited Nations. FAN) 11970 Production Yearbook, 1970. Rome: United Nations. PAID 1971 The State of Food and Agriculture, 1971. Rome: United Nations. Faulkner, Harold U. 1960 American Economic History, 5th edition. New York: Harper. Fe inberg , Richard E . 11372 The Triumph of Allende: Chile's Legal Revolution. New York: New American Library. F0 rbes 14970 "Dark Cloud with a COpper Lining." Forbes (March): 26-28, 33-34, 36' 40. Fortune 1930 Fortune 1936a Fortune 1936b Fortune 1937 Fortune 1 9 51a Fortune 1 9 51b Fortune 1 9 5 1c Fortune 1955 284 "World's Record Fortune "Copper Briefly Considered." Hill." and "Daniel Cowen Jackling." (April): 70-74, 130-132. "Anaconda I." Fortune (December): 83-94, 210, 212, 214, 220. "Copper: World Commodity." Fortune (December): 94-95, 225. "Anaconda II." Fortune (January): 71-77, 134, 136, 138, 143, 144. "Kennecott, Copper, and Cash." Fortune (November): 89-93, 167-168, 170, 172, 175-176. "Kennecott's Titanium Venture." Fortune (Novem- ber): 96-97, 160, 162, 165. "The World of Kennecott." Fortune (November): 84-88. "Anaconda: One Face to the Future." Fortune (January): 89-95, 148, 150. Frank , Andre' ”Gundre 1969 Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press. Frallk, Andre Gundre 15370 "The Development Of Underdevelopment." in Robert I. Rhodes (ed.), Imperialism and Underdevelop- ment. New York: Monthly Review Press. Frank,- Andre Gundre 1972 "Sociology Of Development and the Underdevelop- ment of Sociology." in James D. Cockcroft, A. G. Frank, and Dale L. Johnson (eds.), Dependence and Underdevelopment. New York: Anchor. Franklin, Raymond S. and Solomon Resnick 1973 The Political Economy of Racism. New York: W. W. Norton. 285 Furtado, Celso 1964 Development and Underdevelopment. Los Angeles: University of California Press. Furtado, Celso 1970 The Economic DevelOpment of Latin America: A Survey from Colonial Times to the Cuban Revolu- tion. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. Furtado, Celso l£T72 Obstacles to DevelOpment in Latin America. New York: Anchor. Fusfe 1d, Daniel 11368 "The Basic Economics of the Urban and Racial Crisis." Conference Paper of the Union for Radi- cal Political Economics. Galbraith, John Kenneth 1967 The New Industrial State. New York: New Ameri- can Library. Gal]., Norman 1972 "Copper is the Wage of Chile." AUFS Field Staff Report 19 (April). Galtung, Johan 1970 "A Structural Theory of Imperialism." Journal of Peace Research 2: 81-112. Gedicks, A1 1973 "The-Nationalization of COpper in Chile: Ante- cedents and Consequences." The Review of Radical Political Economics 5 (Fall): 1-25. Gil’-‘ardin, Jean-Claude 11374 "On the Marxist Theory of the State." Politics and Society 412 (Winter): 193-223. G11":‘ran, Norman 11970 "Multinational Corporations and Dependent Under- development in Mineral Export Economies." Social and Economic Studies 19 (December): 490-533. Gll‘van , Norman 1971a Foreign Capital and Economic Underdevelopment in Jamaica. Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research. Girvan, Norman 1971b "Making the Rules of the Game: Country-Company Agreement in the Bauxite Industry." Social and Economic Studies 20 (December): 378-419. 286 Girvan, Norman 1972 Copper in Chile. Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research. Girvan, Norman 1973 "The Development of Dependency Economics in the Caribbean and Latin America: Review and Compar- ison." Social and Economic Studies 22 (March): 1-33. Girvan, Norman and Owen Jefferson (eds.) 11171 Readings in the Political Economy Of the Carib- bean. Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research. Gorz , Andre , 14971. "Colonialism at Home and Abroad." Liberation 16 (November): 22-29. Gough, Ian 15972 "Marx's Theory of Productive and Unproductive Labours." New Left Review 76 (November-December): 47-72. Gramsci , Antonio 15971 "The Study of Philosophy." in Quintin Hoare and Geoffrey Nowell Smith (eds.), Selections from the Prison Notebooks of Antonio Gramsci. New York: International Publishers. Griffin, Keith 15369 Underdevelopment in Spanish America. London: Allen and Unwin. GL1I‘ley, John 1J97l. "Capitalist and Maoist Economic DevelOpment." in Edward Friedman and Mark Selden (eds.), America's Asia: Dissenting Essays on Asian-American Rela- tions. New York: Vintage. Hal'l‘dy, Stanley Thomas :1969 Vertical and Horizontal Structures in the Copper ' Industry. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Michigan State Unitersity. Ha rvey, David , 1973 "Urbanization and the City--An Interpretive Essay." in David Harvey, Social Justice and the City. Suffolk, England: Bungay. Hayter, Theresa 1971 Aid as Imperialism. Baltimore: Penguin. 287 Hendricks, John A. 1922 "The Chuquicamata Ore Body." University of Cal- ifornia Publications in Geological Sciences 14 (September): 75-84. Herfindahl , Orris 11959 Copper Costs and Prices: 1870-1957. Baltimore: Johns HOpkins. Hibbert, A. B. 11965 "The Economic Policies of Towns." in M. M. Postan, E. R. Rich, and Edward Miller (eds.), Economic Organization and Policies in the Middle Ages. Vol. III of The Cambridge Economic History of Europe. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. HObsbaum, Eric J. 11371 "Chile: Year One." New York Review of Books 17 (September 23); 23-32. HObsbaum, Eric J. 1.973 "Karl Marx's Contribution to Historiography." in Robin Blackburn (ed. ), Ideology in Social Science: Readings in Critical Social Theory. New York. Vintage Books. Horowitz , David 11970 Empire and Revolution. New York: Vintage Books. Horowitz , David 1973 "Marx' 3 Approach to the Political Economy of Capitalism." in David Horowitz, The Fate of Midas and Other Essays. San Francisco: Ramparts Press. HOrton, John 1971 "The Fetishism of Sociology." in J. David Colfax and Jack L. Roach (eds.), Radical Sociology. New York: Basic Books. Heulin, David 1968 "Latin America: A Summary of Economic Problems." in Claudio Veliz (ed.), Latin America and the Caribbean: A Handbook. London: Oxford University Press. HYmer, Stephen 1972a "The Internationalization of Capital." Journal of Economic Issues 6 (March): 91-111. Hymer , Stephen 1972b "The Multinational Corporation and The Law of Un- even Development." in J. N. Bhagwati (ed.), Eco- nomics and World Order: From the 1970's to the 1990's. London: Allen and Unwin. 288 ILO’ Yearbook of International Labor Statistics. Geneva: ILO 1955-1971, selected years. Jalee, Pierre :1969 The Third World in the World Economy. New York: Monthly Review Press. Johnson, Dale £1972 "On Oppressed Classes." in James D. Cockcroft, A. G. Frank, and Dale L. Johnson (eds.), Depen- dence and Underdevelopment. Garden City, New York: Anchor. Judis, John 1970 "The Triumph of Bourgeois Hegemony in the Face of Nothing That Challenges It." Socialist Revo- lution l (March-April): 107-125. Kennecott Copper Corporation Annual Report. 1939-1973, selected years. 1