MARKETING BOARD TAXATION. ..~ 1 ; OFNIGERIANAGRICULTURE;_, . ; SOME IMPLICATIONS ; Thesis for 'the Degree of «Ph .. D MICHIGAN STATE UNiVERSlTY FRANCIS SULEMANU LDACHABA . 1972 LID RA R Y Michigan State University This is to certify that the thesis entitled Marketing Board Taxation of Nigerian Agriculture: Some Implications presented by Francis Sulemanu Idachaba has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. fiegreein Agricultural Economics y/ZZWILfil/WW I Majorp/Cesso [ Date ”(/é/7Z 0-7839 "'6‘"; " —.—_’ 1 HOAG'lrSUI'S'" TECC‘K BZN'J‘P‘.’ INC . LIBRARY BlNDKRS I 3 1293 10447 8023 We»? twig/aw r T a T C» “It MHUTI‘HMl M a”; 3 Turn.» u. .. IF {11,13‘ . y T .1» I .1.» 1H- l T mllnMHU?» I: \t-l T.‘ €241 -. :3 t . K _ 7“..- Tu¥_a..‘ - . _ ..2 .io . 1 O I l O . u .1 Mb stud ‘fbr alvw ind \‘r '.O 'h;‘1euune " V . .i‘éunta f 3 MI pr . 2.9" ,, V_ 2” exam.“ , ~: --,A ; Item‘s. arm m 11".»11129 .fa- 3" - '.. .. ,7‘ ,. a v6: (homop- v.7 * 5$§39 '_-{’ fir‘rrdh'r 1" i . _‘»,‘-':4-..- \a 4 ‘ . ‘eitre: 1" Mann! 1:? sacrpcty- , p. .. * extends: r, accaunn by *he mfrmc-nt'ai _’t|... 'Mi‘mtion and fiu}\l.qu~ I'lZ‘IQ-s, the. " Went reunites as; changes in (are; .w, scum-2y eaaea‘ Transmit predicted cub:- '. . c- a (C: 1513.; 5,6531; ‘. -.~r.. ' r ,4. gr" ’ ABSTRACT ‘; W MARKETING BOARD TAXATION OF NIGERIAN Fr" ' AGRICULTURE: SOME IMPLICATIONS BY Francis Sulemanu Idachaba \ r:.: 'A' ‘H - r». at” This study had three main aims: first to prov1de s? I V;_ . 3: “model was developed to explain the effects of "'5 6n the scale of farming in the Northern States i’fias extended to account for the differential fissduisition and salvessjfélyssr the ignitestment responses to Changes in taxes fiftifrfered,‘ in many cases, from those predicted v , 3“ .__ 1:;me , - .J‘ "“3"_ ‘L r»; ra-zclassical mO‘ . . F “. +‘ A: '.e:;.acqu151..cn a 1 . - 1. u 3;. anneal e v e Ilsa-5.5: by r 3;: 1: |.IVF.‘~9"S arr: ‘ It. .ll'v: u-‘bbov A.“ .';:;a. quantities I A.' . p ' . ~ . . - OIO‘H'R‘F ‘“‘~" 5"...Ei bU ELLOOLOKLLI related to ”e 5‘. . "n n “.5 '90.... 4° .m-Nus a re 3’35 ‘0 “Pette Sales 53: b: ; I... 95:.2Ated b. ': Qt.‘ u “.613 CE grO‘J 5.33:.“ -"‘ tG the r -: -.1 it J:.es to tuE *«21 Q‘ “a? ‘3‘5 ‘}b\ U‘ ‘vu i“ _C. ‘ P. “:33. 5‘ V‘t CB‘ ' Q v- I h v. u“?~ . § ‘o “s ‘33 cr‘ n.“ “_ H r Francis Sulemanu Idachaba by the neoclassical model that fails to differentiate between acquisition and salvage values for durable inputs. At the empirical level, these taxes induced cotton and groundnut farmers in the Northern States (1950—66) to use less labor and land than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes. These adverse effects operate at two levels: by reducing the rate of entry of new resources and investments and by increasing the rate of exit of initial quantities on hand. It is shown, within a Cobb- Douglas framework, that compensating subsidies on inputs required to minimize the allocative distortions of taxes are related to the output elasticities of these inputs. This provides a rational basis for relating subsidies on inputs to expected tax rates on marketing board crops. Sales supply equations for cotton and groundnuts were estimated by ordinary least squares. The elasticities of sales of groundnuts and cotton (to the board) with respect to the marketing board's producer price were estimated to be 1.3139 and .9028 respectively. Predictions of sales to the board were made assuming the board paid farmers higher prices than they actually received. These predicted sales exceeded actual sales whenever the hypo- thetical prices were higher than actual prices. These larger volumes of sales together with the implied lower taxes on cotton and groundnuts were used to estimate the (crop tax) revenue impact of paying farmers higher prices. It was found that in many years in the 1950's and 1960's, "‘ .I'fl' I. .. We: prices W0! r' cu: ‘ .u u a" c mu; ‘i‘hOV‘t SUbSt a” at, 11150133 Years: 101‘ 2.575.216 coupled w: I"... I «'LOIT‘I iFACCT-le. fiat. ffect on s: '12! :rzces has n M511 sales t 2::reated as H.212 3.3::- ransom v :ia': :iarces and ccva: 2525 Market mg 5: fin.’ ‘ l“‘\fi 'w-:¢Uu-&Cus from in '3?- ! venues are u. “.3 SPA!“ u.“ .that t \‘ O; I "A" '-~€ ‘qvierfi‘e e‘t ] o; :39”; . ““‘zatlon w -‘ l " .. “’1 . ‘ ‘ Q 530'n'le'im i‘ ‘ L41; the s ale S 2-.15is Sign nals Francis Sulemanu Idachaba these higher prices would have increased farmers' monetary income without substantially effecting tax revenue from the crops. In some years, there were substantial reductions in tax revenue coupled with substantial increases in farmers' monetary income. This Offset to tax revenue loss from the positive effect on sales to the board of paying farmers higher prices has not been analyzed by previous writers. When sales to the board of marketing board crops are treated as random variables, tax revenues from them become random variables. It is shOWn with evidence on variances and covariances of sales Of crops to the Northern States Marketing Board that grounds for expecting revenue contributions from these boards to stabilize State Govern- ment revenues are very tenuous indeed. Using budget data, it is shown that this reliance did in fact destabilize State Government revenues (1956-66) and that the degree of destabilization was consistent with our expectations from apriori knowledge of the supply and demand factors influ- encing the sales of these crops to the boards. The analysis signals the danger of relying on revenue contri- butions from these boards particularly for planned capital expenditures of the States. mmmc BOP-.1 AA AGRICULT'F. Franc1; in h . Mic Hartlal 4 Part: MARKETING BOARD TAXATION OF NIGERIAN AGRICULTURE: SOME IMPLICATIONS BY Francis Sulemanu Idachaba A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agriculture Economics 1972 Dedicated to Aya who made it all possible. ii I an very grate f;:=.::;a‘.1y S‘JPP‘Orting 32:95. I "‘ particul. webeer. very COOPera' Hy ind btemes ’2;::?rcfessor and Th 22%;. His intellectu :erszrel encouragement 3222‘s; infl . uenced my me Ynivers ity . I t : gratitude to him. I l”“ R . A -""55V: 5 Lester V. W “1’ greatest 5..) . unit‘zers ‘ «811 the v .ukiy fruSQ’rat 3:14,“ ‘ -~.e girls - ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am very grateful to the Rockefeller Foundation for financially supporting my graduate studies in the United States. I am particularly grateful to its officials who have been very cooperative and nice in every way. My indebtedness to Professor Glenn L. Johnson, my Major: Professor and Thesis Supervisor, extends beyond this StUdY. His intellectual stimulation, incisive criticism, Personal encouragement and his confidence in me have greatly influenced my entire graduate program at Michigan State University. It is hard for me to adequately express my gratitude to him. I want to thank the following: Professors Lester V. Manderscheid and George K. Dike who read earlier drafts of the thesis; Professor Robert L. Gustafson who was very helpful in the early stages of this study and to Professor Carl K. Eicher who was generally helpful. My greatest debt is to my wife, Aye, on whose shoulders fell the responsibility of looking after a freq"lently frustrated man and also of looking after our two little girls, Achenyo and Qmada. I want to thank them fOr their patience and understanding. .... n- no V" " i ' n- " - . .... I“ casual- O . 'Izfilfl' ‘ q”! rfiy'flmf \! n $."up-JJUG‘LO.‘ o The Role of A: Economy. . Farketing Boa State Cover Official Atti of Marketir Objectives of The Significa Plan of This Footnotes. i-iaE'fl‘ OF FRET-1': Xarketing g. 50! State Petemial p u. TFE Erh'V‘I-h t:t,'\"s C Er“? m JnA\D LA‘XNLI ." nu .' $.‘PYV‘IS 0‘; ' V1,- ‘ {mime 1“ Ti Grit . ‘ “ Pats POOd Crr es: TABLE OF CONTENTS L2,“. “IX" 1‘ JIZT OF TABIIES - s o s o o o o o o c o INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . The Role of Agriculture in the Nigerian Economy. . . Marketing Boards, the Export Sector and State Government Revenues. . . . . Official Attitudes on the Revenue Role of Marketing Boards. . . . . . . Objectives of This Study. . . The Significance of These Problems . . Plan of This Study. . . . . . . .frootnotes. . . . . . . . . . . REVIEW OF PREVIOUS STUDIES. . . . Marketing Boards as Revenue Collectors for State Governments . . . Potential Producer Income and Potential State Government Revenue . . . . . 'Footnotes. . . . . . . . . . . THEEPEECTS OF GOVERNMENT AND MARKETING ' BOARD TAXATION OF CROPS AND SUBSIDIES ON INPUTS ON THE COMMITMENT OF RESOURCES TO - EARNING IN THE NORTHERN STATES. . . . V..;The Effects of Taxes on the Relative ‘ ,.0utputs of Groundnuts, Cotton and Peed Crops. . . . . . . . . . EfféCts of Taxes and Subsidies on :yzquilibrium Amounts of Resources Used. iv 23 28 32 34 35 42 Elasticities a: Comparative St‘ Estimate of Earketinq B: 3 Resource The Bias in E: Got-'errs'ent ;. of Crops a: Resource 115v Production 2 Aggregation P fie Implicit Eq‘ail ibr in: as Our Poin Government a: of Crops a: 'Second-Bes Governent a: 0f Crops E Resources The Data. S‘LTflafy and Footnotes 3'. sexes or ceop GO‘FD“VZT\‘T b.““ Luc‘ mu Taxes Interp‘cti‘ The Deters. cFrom Tax ”ales to t ”vernflfi From the ReSource 1 GOVErnr Chapter IV. \I Elasticities and Their Limitations . . Comparative Statics and Biases in Our Estimate of Effects of Government and Marketing Board Taxation and Subsidies on Resource Use. . . The Bias in Estimates of Effects of Government and Marketing Board Taxation of Crops and Subsidies on Inputs on Resource Use Using a Cobb-Douglas Production Function . . . . . . Aggregation Problems. . . The Implicit Assumption of Allocative Equilibrium: Schultz's Hypothesis as Our Point of Departure . Government and Marketing Board Taxation of Crops and Subsidies on Inputs: A "Second-Best" Problem. . . . . Government and Marketing Board Taxation of Crops Expressed as Taxes on Resources Used in Farming . . . . The Data. . . . . . . . Summary and Conclusions. . . . . . Footnotes . . . . . . . . . . SALES OF CROPS TO THE MARKETING BOARD AND GOVERNMENT AND MARKETING BOARD REVENUE FROM TAXES ON CROPS . . . . . . . Introduction . . . The Determinants of Government Revenue From Taxation of Crops . . . . Sales to the Marketing Board and Government and Marketing Board Revenue From the Taxation of Crops . . Resource Fixity, Supply Response and Government Revenue. . . . . . . Summary and Conclusions. . . . . . Footnotes 0 I I O C O O I I O ESTIMATION OF IMPACT ON GOVERNMENT AND MARKETING BOARD TAX REVENUE FROM GROUNDNUTS AND COTTON OF CHANGES IN THE BOARD'S NET PRODUCER PRICES FOR THESE CROPS . . . Introduction . . . . . . . . . The Model . . . . . . . . . . Page 62 63 64 69 70 100 100 101 105 113 118 121 126 126 128 5:? . wM-‘ied 34cc. fl ntv‘é‘ A. . amt Run “c..- !' “e Long Ron 3“. Er:.rical Pes- Preiiction . n C. Errary ..d Footnotes . v ~ 'n" :v‘ :- 71. mama on. _.. -.-— NY':: 3? SmuE GU.-. Introduction Marketing Boa '3‘. State Go Total State G Without Re‘: Marketing E Errary and C Footnotes . 7.1. 521113.11 REID CZ t7~§lications Footnotes 1"... .Pfls‘ fi.’ nay-.JJ“_.:I: M “fi-Mbdified Model . . . . ";.Short Run Modified Model . 4. The Long Run Modified Model ‘ Bupirical Results. . . Prediction . . . r. »Summary and Conclusions. ' - Footnotes . . . . . _OE STATE GOVERNMENT REVENUES . Introduction . . . _ of State Government Revenue. ‘ Total State Government Revenues ’ Without Revenue Contributions Marketing Board. . . . . ”Summary and Conclusions. . . 5:560tnotes . . . . . . . WSUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . ” Implications of Findings . . Fmtnote s O O O I I O ' With From :MARXETING BOARDS AS POTENTIAL STABILIZERS ‘Marketing Boards as Potential Stabilizers and the Page 135 135 138 140 158 181 185 191 191 192 204 210 215 218 232 235 239 1.3 0‘. vi". ' o’ Connection 0. ' 5% rr; :ores..y, a..- 7‘ ‘.. 5 V“ _ :ro:uc.' 5“C(- Total Value, at Exports to t: fizgeria, 195 Share of Agric Forestry in ' 1930-1968 . The Contributrl CICPS to St; 1956-1966 . T0151 RQVEn‘Je Rehmd to . and Statute NiSeria, 19 Ratios Of COf ‘0 COtton : for lefen 1963/64-19 TC Taxes on ; GIOJDONW 68“» ul'_ Table 1.1. LIST OF TABLES Page Contribution of Agriculture, Livestock, Forestry, and Fishing to Gross Domestic Product, Nigeria, 1950-1968 . . . . . . 2 Total Value, and Contribution of Agricultural Exports to the Agricultural Economy of Nigeria, 1950-1968 . . . . . . . . . 4 Share of Agriculture, Livestock, and Forestry in Total Exports, Nigeria, 1950—1968 I I I I I I I I I I I I 6 The Contribution of Taxes on Marketing Board Crops to State Revenues, Nigeria, 1956-1966 0 O O I I I I O C I. I O 10 Total Revenue and Investment Expenditure Related to Revenue From Marketing Boards and Statutory Corporations, by States, Nigeria, 1970-74. . . . . . . . . . 12 Ratios of Cotton Prices in the Western State to Cotton Prices in the Northern States for Different Grades of Cotton, Nigeria, 1963/64-1971/72 . . . . . . . . . . 26 Effects of Government and Marketing Board Taxes on Relative Prices of Cotton and Groundnuts Produced on Northern States Farms, Nigeria, 1950-1965. . . . . . . 40 Effects of Taxes on Groundnuts on Real (Relative) Prices of Land and Labor Employed on Northern States Farms, Nigeria, 1950-1965 . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 Effects of Taxes on Cotton on Real (Relative) Prices of Land and Labor Employed on Northern States Farms, Nigeria, 1950-1966 . 59 I I 'I nil I 4". w; y . Fartinzer Cons .. "Transating (Fe: for a One Per of a Marketing the Quantity c State Farms C: States, 1930-1 Fertilizer Cons Sigeria, 1966 Unit Tax Elasti Producer Pric Producer Pris Cotton: Tax 9. Respect to t'r CCttOl‘. for [:3 Elasticities iiorthern Sta chun'inuts: '1 RESpect to Price for D 1 , _ . o .. .reolcted Gr: Board priCE TC 1 1967 ' ‘ r '11 r1 — ~ :7 't" (D (1" C! '1 LL 3.4. Compensating (Percentage) Subsidies on Labor for a One Per Cent Decrease in Net Price of a Marketing Board Crop so as to Keep the Quantity of Labor Employed on Northern State Farms Constant . . . . . . . . 78 Fertilizer Consumption in the Northern States, 1950-1967 . . . . . . . . . 86 Fertilizer Consumption in Kano State, Nigeria, 1960/61-1969/70 (Tons) . . . . 87 Unit Tax Elasticities for Cotton Using Producer Prices, Taxes and Potential Producer Price, Nigeria, 1950-1966 . . . 109 Cotton: Tax Revenue Elasticities With Respect to the Board's Producer Price of Cotton for Different Assumed Price Elasticities of Sales to the Board, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950-1966 . . . 110 Unit Tax Elasticities for Groundnuts Using Producer Prices, Taxes and Potential Producer Price, Nigeria, 1952-1964 . . . 111 Groundnuts: Tax Revenue Elasticities With Respect to the Marketing Board's Producer Price for Different Assumed Price Elasticities of Sales to the Board, Northern States, Nigeria, 1952-1964 . . . 112 Predicted Groundnut Sales Assuming Marketing Board Prices at 55 Per Cent of World Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950- 1967 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160 Predicted Groundnut Sales Assuming Board Prices at 55 Per Cent of World Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51—1967/68 . 161 Predicted Groundnut Sales Assuming Board Prices at 60 Per Cent of World Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51-1967/58 (Based on Equation 6). . . . . . . . 162 Predicted Groundnut Sales Assuming Board Prices at 60 Per Cent of World Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51-1967/68 (Based on Equation 7). . . . . . . . 163 viii ”fps-v;p~vb J.Jdu.44enb vs ow. _ *ucaa..y a 'I III R \\ . .3X 16'! The. ‘ Prawnnnwfi JQVIAA‘IOAIU u.’ .. ‘1 . b.dualAY 6 LL .oX Revenu in, '1.) '4 (D ‘34 ’J (I (f (D 3~~ Predicted oard P: Rorthery I ‘1 _. “ a“. «3X “Eve“! From a; Viduall $5. 5.11. 5.12. Predicted Groundnut Sales Assuming Board Price at PN =max (PN 6Pw) where PNj is er Eric the Actual roduc e and Pw is the World Price, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51-1967/68 . . . . . . . . . Tax Revenue: Estimated Changes From Higher Groundnut Prices, Larger Volume, Indi- vidually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950—1965* Tax Revenue: Estimated Changes From Higher Groundnut Prices, Larger Volume, Indi- vidually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950—1965**. Tax Revenue From Groundnuts: Estimated Changes From Higher Prices, Larger Volume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1965 . . . . . . . . . . . Predicted Cotton Sales Assuming Marketing Board Prices at 85 Per Cent of Potential Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51- 1967/68. . . . . . . . . . . . Predicted Cotton Sales Assuming Marketing Board Prices at PN-=max (PNj, .85P ), Northern States, NIgeria, 1950—196 . . Tax Revenue From Cotton: Estimated Changes From Higher Prices, Larger Volume, Indi- vidually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1967 Tax Revenue From Cotton: Estimated Changes From Higher Prices, Larger Volume, Indi— vidually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1967 Variances and Covariances of State Revenues With and Without Revenue Contributions From Marketing Boards and Allied Corpo— rations, Nigeria, 1956-1966 . . . . . ix 164 166 170 172 174 176 177 178 211 v ' ' “ 71:5 1:: ocac: up; a; - a .. agricu.ture a ‘. :-'. ~.. .‘1' .,........al exports :fiexgected future I Lzzllilrg the past ar, Brazing boards and are open ment rev". 3:;ecti'2es of this 5‘ 2.1:“ AC - ‘ sue U‘ thls St‘dc CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION “This introductory chapter briefly examines the i H of agriculture in the Nigerian economy, the role of government revenues. With this background, ‘ Eves Of this study will be stated. Finally, an The Role of A riculture in the Nigerian Economy Agriculture is still the dominant sector in the .:.79 ebonomy. In 1950, agriculture alone constituted . "1 cent of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP); in 1967, {atituted 41.8 per cent. In 1950, agriculture, ‘VJVIiShing, and forestry constituted 67.5 per cent‘ {in-1967 they constituted 55.9 per cent (see From Table 1.1, even when agriculture alone CC- ..o a... «.5. a4.» r.-- oc— 2: . . réo n can t uq- 00— cc“ 0 c.- Nuq! 2‘ 00‘ I 000‘ «CID MOE 3—squula.‘ 1:. . .hholi.it .1L?.Il>ad Quid-flBuHO‘ ICU MS CdethChk 32.:Iufl 5:. .‘h-uoucduuq .5.‘ Chan: HRH Gang than-‘nuh-n I D. ‘u:_:1m—..E -.P-\ .‘NQJUH-JDVLINV< \th's'uA11i \‘rdadu..>flq h..* :II. t I ' D- Iliad-an.u— h§v< o>->I.I-..Lu ‘1....-.qi>d\~ Esau~=ylv‘.h\u‘ 5.: fun-d and... I 9...... Inc [gotten-— In... vnfld... ‘3‘ .II‘O». awful- ulaa I". o ..- in... .- Dillon-s..- '- u on p z s v n u u . I. in o 5. .a..l .l F...‘ a) I ol' newt .lha.'-II|>-u- a'II-tnnavh! Isi‘ Nun. :qu‘ can-id n u-s...vi¢ . u - ~ “JP-IF a.0HA¢H«¢>s nos. 23!: ...a.:.. .mou :H ousuasoauma «0 0.35m on... c.“ .23 we 6:0“... ecu choose 0... us!» as 00:: Dana anon on» an on: :onoau 25: H €09.65 0:» now 5:55..” .93...» uofiumu no anon... Eouu houuflu van» avenues scauguno use nausea. Scams—u one.” Bean on mac uou mouse-Hume £053.30." 5 Juan on: 093960 uouuwb Eouu mcduasnou nuouuoa use» u0u can: :owuguuo uo avonuos cu noucououuup ou mnazo .hmnommd nucaooua Hacoauuz auauumflz. m.onmaxu .O .z .: .ua a: anon» ou canauumaou aduuouav uo: smuomaa you cannons .unou nouOSu ufiuncou Nona us Ono: nousmau Sauna." “nouaum 5mg as one: 032505" union: now nonsuuu he "louoz .Hsaa .saan .Hauma .ou .Ho> .uomun ..m.o.s .uuaunauaum uo uno an .asadnmoaa I .aauou z .nouuu an» o Donna-n: Hanna: .soaaummaa .voaa .uomuq ...m.o.s. nuauuauaum uo uoauuo aqueous .«u=Hu:a smuomma uou nausea» "nonunom 3.: 6.: 6.: 5.: oévm «.02 no: mm 2. 9.: m.nm m.ovm n.5n So." 3 on Dav Evm rims Toma we: 3 2. Q: «Gm n63 «65 no: cm 3 m6. «.3 ~63 To: :3. an no Imv fits Evan 9.95m mom.” .3 cm v.3 «:3 wévw «.3» «woe «a an 7: TS uéno a6: Hum.” ma um I: o.vo En; a6: 83 mm mm 0.3 Tn» oémm m4: an: em .3 We... :23 «Jam «4.3 an: no we Tum .13 we: «.mum 5a.— ; mm v.3 «.3 a6: oémm one." mm no o.mm m.nm Emm‘ n.uhm mmoa no on 0.3 0.3 m6: mémm en: so co.— o.um «.3 ~43 wéum mm: mm mm «.mm v.3 s6: «:33 «m3 co." «3 .15. IS «.2. 5.3m 3a..” 2: o3 o.um .515 adon o.mov on: 2: I omaa u:uu mom :3. 2m 5:23..» use .Euuouom 3.03.3.3 ousuasuauz .50 no scant—omens ands-uh use 35,330.74: mac «0 cannon—cum a as 952..."..— uss china—6:3 .huu-goh £09553 us.» a no mucus—6E0: .buuouom .xoouno>.3 ensues—Owns no :oausfluucou uo Mensa oneumaoauu< .336an dun-3: Jon—nous own-088 :05 ca 8.3-: v:- Iran-ouch £03.25.— .ousuusoquud «0 83:33:81.”; 3 ::::s‘.ie:ed (excmdir‘ 22.321 of the econ/3:7; 22:-2:32: position t' _ mar-acted indice s acti‘g'it iES' the‘ r:::: LPEOE agricUlt" 22::orce ard it is‘ 22:22: pin period, a .‘s‘: a; will still ;::;e::ed GDP.1 The export cor- u:. . 3.15.3:1cal 1y 1:9: .:... exports origina ...... o IIIII fiance. those 6 €1.36?) +L t 1 we} had .3: .iLQ 1_2) . Ty. 2L1} .erne . 15. yalm c a: “Gig 2 “ 0 ‘ 8 PE: 1": ,a ' 3-: Ft. “"111 1 '9. '1 is considered (excluding livestock, forestry, and fishing), its dominant position becomes evident. As indicated by the constructed indices of the share of agriculture and allied activities, there is a declining trend in the importance of agriculture. Yet, agriculture is still the mainstay of the economy, employs about 70 per cent of the labor force and it is projected that at the end of the current plan period, agriculture, livestock, forestry, and fishing will still account for 44.2 per cent of the projected GDP.1 The export component of the agriculture sector has been historically important and is still important. In 1950, exports originating in agriculture, livestock, and forestry sector totaled LN80.345 million; in 1960, at Independence, those exports totaled LNl4l.478 million and by 1965, they had reached an all-time high of LN163,663,000 (see Table 1.2). The items underlying Table 1.2 are cocoa, palm kernels, palm oil, beniseed, goat skins, cattle hides, cotton (raw), rubber, fresh bananas (mainly up to 1960), timber logs, sawn timber, plywood and veneers, groundnuts and groundnut oil and groundnut cake where the last two items are included for completeness. These exports as a percentage of total value of agriculture in GDP were 20.8 per cent in 1950, 27.1 per cent in 1954, 21.6 per cent in 1966, and 24.5 per cent in 1967 (GDP valued at 1962 factor cost), maintaining a proportion of GOA I .26... Lo..- Omo~ A. ~v ANV A.~\-v Fh‘ ’=‘-. -L AIM-W. \ ‘.> \N _. . U:«ZI«L VII .>vaILC§ LCD Cu .M..II~CL .1..C.I..w>u.~ finalih3.‘ 32‘ 14:.- .‘ L-I‘> slcnvuInvur—‘u s--:.~:...qhnr‘ -anU-qafi.‘ .~v< L: -5~'> r . u : \'.~=u~:.eq-\a< h.» Is,~:.~IE 66-.IL- Idh...nXu_- 54v h... ','~.~-...-Iv.- o-:d-—.u<- -< h - -< N: 0-3—‘3 '5A') h.~ 1-91:! | In: I.-...¢Xv- -=-|> 5.. ‘Ny‘..::-.~h m ' III‘ 'o n... It .l": n1". o'c CCU-1.2 so.- >‘.|-1-.p...|l -II no: o-oou-uiivl‘ ‘a. I .t. ' Olav-III 'Il‘lu- 0-...I‘i,‘ .hnu .I‘.‘ can... I coho: - .d-u' I‘Qi‘-) .6 .9}? . I 1‘ . u ‘Q‘c’? 5011.325 uo:.. 2.30:. -.¢.:.. "ouoz 500.3“. «m ucuuu:oo uu unoo uouoau can» nonuau TS «Em TC How umoo uououu ”£05.50 an no: «wrong nan n:o«ua«oo«ao now anon no «cow—«s moo :« ass»: «:3 .huunouOu £00302: .ouou«=o«umu mo os«u> 0:» van» :« >«o>«uoumn0u «3 «Eu .5 Scan uouflé «.«v and «.5 .«.« o«nd.«. oon $09.50» 2.0:» 50.3 utgxo o cum u o o :o um :0 so now owns a: no; one :« 95:03 «:3 ~aha-0.3M .xoou-obfin .ausu«ou«um0 mo 02«u> now .33 .33 .wu«um«unum mo nonhunnd «3:34 :85 counofioo noun—36 .933 no on«c> “oounom .m:..£u«h can .huunou0h .xOOuno>«.« .0u=v«50«nm< 2.9505" one: .«0H9u«ao«um4-u .3 .1: 6.: .1: 6.: 2342 83 «3 m.«« m.v« «.3 «.o« on«.««« 53 «o« «.«« o.«« v.3 o.o« ¢««.ov« no: vo« m.v« «.«N «.3 «.3 «ow.«w« no: a: m.«« «.«« «.o« «.5 oo«.«m« =3 «3 v.«« m.«« «.3 «.3 o««.on« «om.— hm« n.«« «.3 «.3 «.3 «o«.w«« «o«« «5 9: v.«« o.a« «.5 ovm.o«« «mg 2." «.m« o.«« o.o« 5.: «Sin: 33 a: «.3 «.m« «.«« «.o« o««.«v« «m3 4 a: m.«« w.«« «.3 «.5 «:6: «mo« v«« v.«« v.«« o.«« o.«« u««.ho« 53 n: u..« w.v« w.o« w.o« «mo.m«« om: ««« m.«« m.«« v.«« v.«« m««.o«« mm: «o« «.5 «.5 «.«« «.«« «w«.o«« on: ««« m.«« w.«« «.o« «.o« «34.3 «m«« o: w.m« o.m« o.«« o.«« m««.««« «mm« o«« «.c« «.o« m.o« m.o« «3.2: «mg oo« «.3 «.o« «.5 «.5 «on...» on: oo« .. omm« ucoo you «.3: an «.2 3V «.3 .«v mag-«.— 65 §uuu0uo~ «no :« moo :« 9.3-: c:- ioouogflu .0Mou«=o«uu< 9.335033 «0 031' tau-ouch .xuounofifi aka-ouch is. £03.25.— loun nukes no we omcu:00uom Gauguin: «0 355.33.»: «0 canon—nu no.» . 2 3«o> no sconu c an 3.396 oa«c> no 0o¢ucoou0m «.2 no 31> c an nun—OE .3973: 3.3032 «0 «lacuna «ounu«=u«um¢ on» 3 school” dauguauuni no co«unfl...uu:ou u:- .Qs.nc> «003......«4 a 51:: one-fifth for =;:::::tion of tot rzszzck, and fish 3.3;:2 cent in 19 u- uto~r~ but Ann. .:0.:vvauh on UUUA gears to be a 5.6 12:21 exports. Tazle 1.3 figure. livestcc 25.11; YE'EXport “2.33314 5 ac 5 about one-fifth for the period of nearly two decades; as a proportion of total value of agriculture, forestry, livestock, and fishing in GDP, these exports amounted to 17.3 per cent in 1950, 23.3 per cent in 1954 (partly reflecting the boom periods for primary products in world markets around this time), 16.8 per cent in 1966 and 16.2 per cent in 1967. In this latter series, there appears to be a declining trend in the share of agri- cultural exports. Table 1.3 shows the share of exports from agri— culture, livestock, and forestry in total exports (in- cluding re-exports) for the years 1950-68. Up until 1960, these exports accounted for well over 80 per cent of all Nigerian exports annually, with an all time high of 89.1 per cent. As from 1960, there is evidence of a declining trend, reaching only 51.5 per cent of all exports in 1966. We expect this decline to continue with increasing exports of petroleum2 and increasing domestic use of some agricultural exports. Nigeria displays great diversity in agricultural resource endowments.3 The agricultural economy of the Northern States can be divided into cropping subregions according to climate and ecology: (1) land where ground- nuts and food crops like guinea corn, millet, beans, etc. are grown; (2) land where cotton and food crops are grown; (3) land where cotton, groundnuts and food are produced, OCH “EMUvU -Nnxonm fififi: 2‘ \ @«2 Hi OOH .I Unrnwd 72!. OUBOQXE Cnuuh d4< lune :terCnqux-rbrn I. If: :1“. w athvdz Rise) ma U -u 33X: .fihuvnurflhnuau ~oJ-.;u~:,deth< said-«mispri 7:1. uni 53.0 Haiti» - hug/K . 13?. . I€> «A .R 0....UFHvu5 a InuAUU-eunv) ¢.H --0.-uu Ind arugu‘rn on. .lu 'Ii:-I.... . A ---I‘ \V-‘u..-l“>-.h Ins€ivhcl4huu II-I‘ ill . Ill.ll.\l~... ‘ . I u N CI-III\- ..nn...nafi..- -v\ .N.H manna 0mm .>uummuom can .xooumo>aa .musuasofiumm mo wuuomxm mo wsHm> mom .moma .vwma .mmmH .mowmq ..w.o.m .moaumfiumum mo uomuumnd Hudccm .mwuswfim uuomxw cmHummflz Hmuoe "mousOm oh m.Nm mmo.HHN mwma Hm n.vm mam.avn nwma mm m.am mmo.vmm coma mm o.Hm www.mom mood mu m.on omw.vHN vwma vm v.mm www.mwa mood vm o.m> mmm.moa Nwma om m.mn www.mna Homa em v.mm vah.moa coma mm m.nm hmv.moa mmma mm m.>w 0mm.mma mmma mm m.¢m VMm.hNH bmma ,6 mm m.mw mnm.qma wmma vm m.mm vam.mma mmma mm o.nm Nmm.mva «mma hm m.mm NMN.¢NH mmma hm n.0m omm.mNH mmmH mm h.mm voo.o~a Hmma ooa H.mm mum.om omma ooH u omma ucoo you Hafiz zm huumoNOh was muuomxm sawummwz .xuoumo>wq .musuasoflumd Had no wmmucoouwm m mm muuomxm Scum muuomxm zuumwuom can .xUOumo>Hq cwwuomfiz snow no oumnm mo xwvcH .wusuasufiumm scum muuomxm Hmuoa .mwmalomma .m«uomfiz .muuomxm dance :a auumUHOh can .xooumo>flq rousUHaoHde mo oudnmll.n.a Mandy 1,; Lad in the v. :12: at some grains its Sachem State :25: {1) land uhe 55:5 Si. 93‘... a. :.L_:a'.:, rather, a: care 3.51.113: oil pa . I "“" ":r' -a-¢u.'.. n.' '0" "‘5 orig'r‘al I..'~‘n no: Quit . I “"4. u H ‘ I . 6".u' . * “ 11110 the '1. ‘ I’Hg . Nata: frcpl ‘d"‘ ‘ ‘ .r A“ I -,. . ’CVI‘ I‘l' I" ‘k I ‘ ‘ I sat: L..e 3‘ 13 . u "U rr Cw ..' q ‘1: F ‘ ‘ .- tb h.‘at r J ‘v ‘A :u'e-S I tanc'] - 4 “A i" v. §..‘ “ “‘ tfc. ‘ . :3"!- I' uv . "a‘azl and (4) land in the Middle Belt where mainly root food crops and some grains are grown. The agricultural economy of the Southern States can be divided into four production zones: (1) land where cocoa and food are grown; (2) land where oil palm and food crops are produced; (3) land where oil palm, rubber, and foods are produced; and (4) land where mainly oil palm, rubber, cocoa, or foods are produced. Marketing Boards, the Expggt Sector and State Government Revenues It might be argued that it is now irrelevant to go into the original intent for setting up the marketing boards. Not quite. In June, 1971, the report of the Study Group on Oil Palms4 felt a need to go "a little deeper" into the original laws establishing the marketing boards from which it concluded that "unless the law governing the marketing board is changed . . . there can be no improvement in the industry." Arguments about the origins of the marketing board system have become very extensive.5 Both in the Cocoa White Papers6 and subsequent legislation, it is evident that some form of stabilization of producer prices, money or real income was intended as a primary goal within the general framework of securing "the most favourable arrangements for the purchase, grading, export “, '3"! View he 51% academicians 1: acre cases :5 setting up of '-‘- "as stated: the first cha: working capit. ' - . Price 3 Prmary aim 0 resources am~ CEPital have By the ti :"thaes had Sw‘ ‘: “a 'n. in . w contrlbld. :9} . u, ~94: “R -¢3;3 Board 31"‘9‘13 Sign“ a 5“ l‘:- . . "“NEC to tells “21:: fig ‘ Fred -. ,ie a .{j . pV" CL t » ~.:Pq s'a‘ A 't y “‘ ""5: .‘fl 5v S‘ La‘ 5 , . f ‘J'K u'h “‘brfi'}- ‘ ¥‘°‘ «1’ and selling of . . . cocoa, and to assist in the develop- ment by all possible means of the cocoa industry . . . for the benefit and prosperity of the producers."7 Official Attitudes on the Revenue Role of Marketing Boards The view has now evolved, among policy makers and some academiciams alike, that price stabilization was not, and in some cases should not, be the main objective behind the setting up of the marketing boards. In the EEEEE Annual Report of thgggigerian Groundnut Marketing Board, it was stated: The first charge on the board's funds must be for working capital to finance its purchases of groundnut. . . . Price stabilization must always constitute the primary aim on the board's actual and prospective resources after the critical requirements of working capital have been met. By the time of the First Development Plan, attitudes had swung almost full circle. After spelling out the contribution of the (then) Northern Nigeria Marketing Board to its capital development program, the Northern Nigerian Government 1962-68 Development Plan planned to relieve "the board of its liability for subsi— dizing the producer price of crops in lean years, and fixing producer prices annually at such a level in relation to world prices as to anticipate a surplus on the year's operations to cover operating costs." The plan went on further to state that "the marketing board will inevitably look increasingly to Nigerian sources to provide the :.;::-terr. credit re "72;:;,'9 W0 thi 5:5:;r~g boards ha 525‘. sup. uses f axis: tce Stat 25 regianalizatio :::::c:. to see t 1'13“; agital ds “f revenue 32:13: to a prod titre of Specif 937539 F“ ocat l( 1"?” GEE-t of e 06 credited 5““? States .w .11 Per Ce‘.t as if." “'P "J Parts; n: :_a L ’A -S a “2‘4 an” +: '“b‘Or S . Erhva ads; *‘ bEYGS \H ' M. I'.‘ I .a“~E Q s"“ 0'.- 'L.“IC.v-_‘ x. -S r x it; ."Er :3 Fr y‘zr l ‘h. ”affine. -h‘r‘: 'P a uv short-term credit required to finance crop purchases and movement."9 Two things have occurred: first, the marketing boards have come to treat the so-called surpluses as real surpluses freely to be used by the marketing boards and the State Governments at will.10 Second, with the regionalization of marketing boards, State Governments have come to see them as sources of revenue for their various capital development programs. In addition to this source of revenue from crops, export crops have also been subject to a produce sales tax and an export tax that is a mixture of specific and ad valorem rates. Under the New Revenue Allocation Decree retrospective April, 1969, 40 per cent of export duties on commodities other than oil will be credited to the distributable pool while the producing states will receive 60 per cent, instead of 100 per cent as previously. The pool will then be divided into two parts: one-half to be divided equally between the states and the other half to be divided on the basis of population.11 Olakanpo and Teriba imply a strong positive correlation between the existence of marketing board institutions and the imposition of produce sales taxes and exPort taxes on export crops.12 Table 1.4 shows the relative dependence of State Governments on marketing board crops (we shall henceforth refer to crops subject to marketing board control as marketing board crops because for some of these crops I3CC>§3 I; «C a: I . .1... ~32 .55.).z IO-I one. 3-.Iullfl C. l._....u CHIC: I3C0>SK C. ILC~L Quark. I3EI>IK {a 1;, :5 : ’C—H.X.II :3 I‘XIH. iu‘oaehu ’Cv «tax-E! u... Iii-the ~CbCL. Dn-‘usxh‘z :3 .QX'H‘ ~¢6r\l. he.» c..w&=-«~.d:.o.v has C..u barandh canary LC Cguv bah-u .n puff... "d'aa nuh'JI.“I I'o‘umu u.~.l!—dh..2 flaw—D“ :h‘ul". "n-suvaO- .‘an'nvcz .I--.:nl>" -u'tfl- .ut I.-a..:hrb ‘h'c‘ bruub-luu-! :c .‘X'Lr has {AU-.Uanuuulflcco -P-L. o'.~ I.H:<..F n.0Hnnflucbu uoc. cases 3.1.:. "ouoz .aunum shay-ox cad uuaum mom-A pouaumsoo ua .nmma nouns louuum wound was .0uuum uucslpw: .ouuum cuouwoz accuoum any as: noma Have: a: :oHuuu cuouuot 6H0 0:9 .ouduauconxo can. nos—.95.." Hasuoa Ban—«acumen banana 03"qu ninauocou aqua—5000‘ on» Gown :9?» dado .m.o.h 05 0.3.5» nouns—«yum uomunn can” hon» oasouon 3 was... managnuum .93» on» «0 =05 who...» Eouu unuuwu non—:25..— ouuua noun; a) csomuouuoo uo: 0v macauanauucoo omaucoouom .ha .m ..UaAH .nouuon aauoxud: 0:» mo iceduloua 95.3qu: no uncausfluucou eunucoouom 6;." .33». 30.35036 no an. an $me .33 .nomuq ..m.o.m .auzuaunum no young-n: H5552 £35500» aquamuu v.3 acouusov 02:33— uuaum .309. Mon "cannon .l.: «co.~n .u.: nmv.v~ win on“. ma moan min nvv.ou .n.: th.an néu hum. 5N moo." h.oN mnn.NN N.NN nhn.on «Una 0.34.3 voma at: oGw.ON v.v~ «Nh.wN H.Nu hhm.vu mood 0 a.Nn FOH.NN o.mN ooméu N4. ovaéu «and 1 dig nnméfi N.@H mum.wu m.ow one...“ HuoH «.mn wmm.o.n mén aoanN mév vroéu can." mi...” 6.3.1" h.mN mpm.mu o.on ovnfia «mm.— w.m.n oun.n.n h.vN nnh.w.n m.mN no.2” 0mg” 0.0N vnH.NH «Eva avatnn n.vn muo.vv hmad a.vu wood otnu avr.n.n h.on Hon.v.n omod ufluu Hon Add: 2.“ undo now Add: a 080 “Oh HHH! a ouco>ox sou-um Emu-um 09:25.» nouuum 52.3.32 35:3— Hanna—won ou nmouo canon 09:25: 3 30.6 933 3:25: 0» nuouu Econ 332,3 has» 9303.5 :0 nouns Hanan. weaves—nu: so .939 Hanan. 93387.3: no can. A-uoa no couunauusou «o gausnuuucoo no soda—afluucoo nouuum Econ-a nouavw cuonuuoz sown!" Eon-OB 63.732 .3332 33:26.. 3-3.. on :66 canon 2.38.: no non-u. no coaunfluugoo 3.7-...” 33 n‘ a ‘ VT: :vetw‘l o ‘* LY A ' "' 7 Fur 2:55 :;~J&e)| ‘ 11 nrr :ii'tso-ca..ed 5a., teting board I crud-D it. :Me {:65 asserts" :.-; 1 1.2211961-62. Eéiiince reac‘: ed air: of 14.1 per “1:3: ‘Ia -~= :ms relat 21:1‘1958‘59 aj :::;::ihg to t‘ Le For the 5 fig" ti... ...:.e....g boards D... d“. [A] ”“9 (Table .5“ ‘A v-IiTru'e Far-YE k“ .u Eastern C 412 .. 5 U'as. ' F e 5 P15 15 : «qafis 3b deper‘r ‘3‘». "Mt"? ll like cotton, only a very small proportion will be exported in the future). For the purposes of this study, marketing board so-called surpluses are seen as taxes on the producers of marketing board crops. By 1960—61, revenues from taxes on crops in the Western State and Lagos State accounted for 60.5 per cent of total financial resources of the State Government; this dependence reached a low of 7.2 per cent in 1961-62. In the Eastern States, this relative dependence reached a high of 27.8 per cent in 1961-62 and a low of 14.1 per cent in 1962-63. In the six Northern States, this relative dependence reached a high of 29.9 per cent in 1958-59 and 15.6 per cent in 1960-61 (we are here referring to the old regions in the terminology of the new ’ states). For the Second Development Plan period, the marketing boards are expected to play an even more impor- tant role (Table 1.5). In the 1970-74 Development Programme, marketing boards and statutory corporations (mainly financed by marketing boards) provide more than one-third of the total internal government revenue re— sources in Western, South-Eastern, and Kwara States; in South Eastern State these sources account for one—half of the State's planned investment expenditure. Rivers State is least dependent on marketing boards and statutory corporations as sources of revenue. (Kano and South- Bastern States would have deficits rather than surpluses A a at In. III-‘I .l 0-15.)-.. ‘3‘ a. 2.1. :39 >n..fi3 a. a“. Finn. Fv b'nv‘ .3. uIlth lip-d!- ..-'n- 'CI’P‘|'I .'l .vh-l I'CIII,IVA uCI . .2..- 1...!" .uflduw‘CILII U:"-I'>C— .025. ‘1 ditch lit—I '3 . .' U-h-‘a'-\oc— 1.. 12:... F.-‘." uni! 'LI-anh.‘ .‘o unlit-..- u lel‘lII-v- >1II. 0.40-... Dunn- "I'tvll in. n'.-.. . I1- . 4.1.5.1.... 6"...- oII>Cn fl. inn-h. ,!-1.I-I I! III.‘ UC.I.-.>pv3 Cola: L: SEIDQK ~‘uGF &.. ‘\.|u-...-.Ia- I I. '::‘>'I I‘A4-U‘-.lnn.... *I..bo—U'O.m “you. Ian'Avql IrnquI-II! -Iog')! I'd IIIIU‘IIIIQ ' In) .0 i'ln-n.lu Ida‘d'?‘ fl'Uu-".J i'£ 1. fps. .CA.~ t'hAIn- ¥.-..u-.~'~I b.'.-'ao: III- --l~'! ivl.‘ -anb-\r“ 0C!~C)S .- .1 T... ~1h 'u-").‘ «'0.‘ 0.5!. -:8 OIJ ‘0' at. Inh""'\l-II Ivafi‘ ‘l4-'\a" I "Ifbull .l . I .III‘.’ 12 .HO« .m .orod .005 .aofluafiuounn uo aha-.15: Hugh .vhlohad 5am a v.5” n.«.n «ION tvu >6 o.n a... quota— ni. or: n.9— m.w« wé «.n «Kn Hula-id! o. «.3. «.« m.m.n 0.9 $4 1nd 53:.“ g '6 «.ma v6 odd n6." o.n o.o« Ice-A w.on min 0.3: «.3. m6." 0.0 n h 1.5on scan w.n.. 9.3.. v.« adv H.0H 0.0 h.«v call méu Sn.— n.nu o.vu 0.: n n via 533 fine: «.0: 1m." 05. 1.3 0.3” « n v..n« g €03 0.3: 0:: rd: Ton m6." « n v.3 Hug Auto. Ema h; $.17 «.5 min a o n.« g in at?“ n6 «:3 nén 0.: m an glen—6m o.«n «.3 OJ: «.«h v2: 0.0« o no goal «.3: In 0600 won «.3: In 0600 now and. a 3325— 55.38.98 9305 nun—«80¢ 83-838 salvo->3 3.8 no .7396 hug-um 38. no H32. 33: cog->0: 108. so can veal-g can canon glaucoma.— - .- nsects“— !!an uo coca—loud.— gluonuoo 33a 88 E nae-bound: 35: on: . «duos Sign a u- g 33.53% all:- 330 a Cong... 9:0: “as Gui 309 3305.30 .3 39.— 063013: #3033» on. g 9.33 8.33.3: Sun 3'»! ( s ~ .252...— 3103.‘ ecu-nu «a 3.3393930 Ens-an 1:- ion angul— Ivuh ill o» go- 053 0"; 1a- .n.n . 255135;:er ccrpc salable to these 3:: Central, Ncr1 32322522111 have I: mating board ar. IE'.'E.‘.‘.29.) Table 1 733:5 state gov The Keste: rezeigts for cap: E3‘.;e:ia Marketin: mm Prices, 1231:2111 adequat. g... | "1.6 S developr‘ 0n the a 3:33.21" 5%,. u ‘ utvuid I. NC! f”Tia-tic” 331:)..." «ufille Evid teyk :PliCat: 30v . 1.25 ls their - 5“ 13 On total current and capital account if marketing board and statutory corporation sources of revenue were no more available to these state governments; East Central, Kwara, North Central, North Eastern, North Western, and Western States will have much larger deficits in the absence of marketing board and statutory corporation sources of revenue.) Table 1.5 shows the projected dependence of various state governments on marketing board crops. The Western State Development Plan 1970-74, statesl 3 that "as at present, the main source of internal receipts for capital development remains the Western Nigeria Marketing Board" and that in determining net producer prices, "emphasis would be given to the need to marshall adequate revenue from this vital area to aid the state's development effort." On the academic side, Helleiner states that "growth should have carried greater weight in Nigerian policy formation than stability, and there exists no conclusive evidence that the two are correlated."14 Teriba and Olakanpo have stated that "one important fiscal implication of the regionalization of the marketing boards :is their conversion from potential stabilizers of Producer prices into potential stabilizers of Regional G°VernInent Revenue."ls Policy makers being so concerned about the revenue I”tential of marketing boards and their allied statutory ("it 1’ .rs n-Jv - «craticns have ~::::: and sales m‘nt - ”.v- .er‘fi $.5‘ wine vow-1.950 :W‘i ens of z: .::.f-OV - i : .‘Vf fig. 5533 0'. ma. me u .L N." F... v r- ~r‘. a La! ioub‘ r‘U.‘ s .-:" F'f" '10.! 3"“ . o .w:' 9%. “-..Hre "" uni 5"“. .'-:”: fly”, 17 I!‘.‘ .‘Ur . h: “h"! F‘ no hv‘.-_le‘.ba "H35; “"39 Price :‘a‘nal . . ....;.is 13.911: :3.” 'fl‘: A u “ “nua LY o ‘F 1.53:9 :‘W . “‘ can. “LJS‘ S ‘ I “Q I U fi’fl in.‘ c‘ s U“ ( K 5"; '«b :r:f:whn I “A v. s u 2"“. .‘ '- -- R § A..." mpg“ d av‘bu. d . V ‘ a“, ‘ a N : e5, ‘ P C. ‘ ‘ {4&4 'PE ‘ .“ ”-v 14 corporations have not bothered themselves with the negative output and sales effects of the heavy taxes on marketing board crops. Their policies are based on the implicit assumptions of zero price elasticities of supply and/or sales of marketing board crops. Recently, state governors and other public officials have expressed grave concern over what they term the "falling output" of marketing board crops.l6 This, it seems to me, is really a concern over the future of the revenue potential of marketing 17 board crops. On the academic side, though Helleiner in his monumental study18 admits of the possibility of positive price supply elasticities, the core of his analysis implicitly assumes zero price elasticities of 19 Nowhere in the liter- supply of marketing board crops. ature is the possibility of drastically cutting down taxes on crops, raising producer prices and still leaving state government and marketing board revenue from agriculture substantially unaffected thoroughly discussed. There is an absence in the academic literature of any analysis of the effects of taxation of marketing board crops (represented by the marketing board surplus, the produce sales tax and the export tax) on the scale of farming measured either in terms of acreages or size of lab“? employed. But this problem has become increasingly imp°rtant in recent years as farmers have reallocated res(“tees to different crops in response to differential .z. vates on these .4- a u- governcrs a: 5:219 increasmg -.¢~:!;I“"s if‘ ‘ hunt-tnlb “b L . 94.0?pr 9" fr .uVR “vow“: kll' r.OCub ‘ -!-':n- It «G u: 'I!I.lloe uh at u , 23 fuovv=o -. ,- U The firs “'4'"; g ......e a frame" at" fin; ,_ e s - u.‘ h.c:.f‘e‘ » “ l'ru‘ II. c n V .“r“"‘ 0-6 .I h bu. .fi‘ ' w awllCdtir \ "' "t ’P“n ‘ . g‘Vu;:I‘t‘ l“ "h. ' JCHL a Er“ ~a .‘r: ‘ - in ad‘bn fi'f.“ 3~ Junr N ‘I I 6 a": ‘e. ' “‘91 w p p ‘ we '. autc“ Q». \.~ filters q v Q“: ‘ I: ‘ v~ §,. \l‘e ?;v‘ “I“ V. “i: 3‘ ‘ ‘s 15 tax rates on these crops. In the Northern States, state governors and other public officials are worried at the increasing diversion of land acreage away from groundnuts into food production resulting from substi— tutions in production in response to the effects of government and marketing board taxes on relative crop prices.20 Objectives of This Study The first objective of this study then is to provide a framework for examining the effects of govern- ment and marketing board taxation of crops and subsidies on inputs on the commitment of resources to production, with application to the use of land and labor resources . on the groundnut and cotton farms of the Northern States. More specifically, the framework will be addressed to the following questions. What have been the effects of these taxes on the supply, "retirement," or salvaging of used resources from and disinvestment in these resources (on, Northern States farms? Have these taxes tended to induce groundnut and cotton farmers in the Northern States to use exactly the same, more, or less of land and labor thatifliey would have used in the production of these crops in the absence of these taxes and subsidies? If policy flakers (are willing to live with the institutional reality °f the Inarketing board system but are anxious to minimize the a1locative distortions of these taxes with respect to ‘ ‘- ':E:.::e use, “3a \- a ,c:A"'f‘e5? A I .¢UU“' {52:15 of differf :32 relative 0‘ Tne seccr. {2:22th zga qr :t'pn in“ d m-‘n.u “‘3 “Ha: t , . ----- g . A 1 .45.”; Jitters h. ' n mg... m‘n ' Juvgfiec| tells ‘ .; a"! .. «u the (ere -v‘~‘ .23... .amers * 5. 22:52:, ‘1; .. 6 Ac ' op .‘h ~ ...e beard. Given p p ..,_ 3:”..P'u .hmfints on ‘1" . ‘(c“.ln W3 boar: 'b.; N»: ' Varies I 2:5 3b.. ‘ be: ‘1 the 53be ‘H . *I«Stec ..A‘ v... LN» ‘ awed wi tad? . ‘43 r v . t~3blen 16 resource use, what are the required compensating subsidies on resources? A related question is: what have been the effects of differential tax rates on cotton and groundnuts on the relative outputs of these crops? The second aim of this study is to examine the quantitative impact on Northern States Government and marketing board tax revenue from cotton and groundnuts of paying farmers higher prices than the actual prices they received. This will enable us to examine to what extent, if any, the (crop tax) revenue loss that results from paying farmers higher prices can be offset by the positive effect, if any, of higher prices on sales of these crops to the board. Given past and planned dependence of many State Governments on contributions (loans and grants) from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations for their various State Development Plans the third aim of this study then is to examine whether these contributions can be trusted to stabilize state government revenues over projected plan periods as has been recently suggested. This problem is important for the stability of State Government operations and even political stability in the future. ...e 81' __....—— Auseful ( agricai measare effects of tnese aside epolicy d :z‘lcrtnen Stat ”' '7’” Hf: * S u u... «gunman,» ‘ u- :a~* ‘;at a” ‘1'. Let .‘ u! o... \ F‘P‘_ v d not .uE JG: 5“ -nL 2" ' v‘ A ' ctgoc {late-e“ 1.. r I. V: :(p‘o‘l .I \ ".over '5. urban areas. to isvest ;:::easir.gly ch 353515 also c 3:11;? gal CI oVu--‘ n E . 1’ he“ U v -Q “as: . I a: 3;.Q “"S F‘ v‘ C, '9 :v' ne‘flet‘ll F . .g an, N’. ~.:C.>.“ ‘ .‘ '- ‘ Sbahcl‘h ..j a 5.15 P . ‘ F v 17 The Significance of These Problems A useful conceptual framework provides a basis for empirical measurements. Empirical measurements of the effects of these taxes on resource use are necessary for sensible policy discussions. There is mounting concern in the Northern States over the diversion of acreages away from groundnuts and cotton to other crops and also over the fact that in some states such as the North—East State and the North-West State, suitable additional land has not been planted in these crops. . Unemployment is currently a serious problem. There is concern over the drift of farmers and youth from rural to urban areas. Rural people deciding (at the margin) where to invest their future labor time are known to have increasingly chosen the non-farm, urban labor market. There is also concern over the slow transformation of traditional agriculture in Nigeria. Why are few farmers adopting new recommendations, or buying new inputs, etc.? These are all issues a good conceptual framework should help throw light on. We have no estimates of the price responsiveness of sales of cotton and groundnuts to the Northern States Marketing Board. Yet this knowledge is crucial for an understanding of the responsiveness of tax revenue from these crops to changes in the board's price. hm regar :erecen: experie giggle. POI the Ezaze, 'cagital r 23:: of estimate "we" ,1, gr‘v 1 .95 I ”tn-avu. o s . h‘, :n‘ \vudr -er :::;:;s as they . " 3’7! “"mz’ listed I :apte be. :-:‘-. .‘ . “Mme *' e 2153 or. cr OPE 55.6 of -”o'.. _I 4. Intern Q N “‘n ‘\ s F .n; ‘lie Ch‘r Ir V~~ “mm Hm" Fr L‘s... ‘~ GIL ‘ ~ ‘I‘ P R.- vflwgri ; t 5 ‘PI u W. U..: S to t": s.‘ \_ '3 o. A - n ‘Vus .. are .- A‘s ‘5 :Ci' :‘I p: I .L‘ b\th a Pv- U. ‘I 1.". I V. "kes V‘Ev-s ‘Q 18 With regards to the third objective of the study, the recent experience of the Western State is a good example. For the 1971-72 budget year for the Western State, “capital receipts of some EN 7 mill fell EN 5 mil] short of estimates because the state of world markets, particularly for cocoa, made it impossible for the marketing board to make a contribution. . ."21 Plan of This Study Chapter II will review previous studies. Short- comings as they relate to the themes of this study will be briefly listed. Chapter III will present the framework for analyzing the effects of government and marketing board taxes on crops and subsidies on inputs on resource use and scale of farming in the cotton and groundnut farms of the Northern States. A production function approach is used With the Cobb-Douglas serving as an example. Chapter IV develops the theme that in examining problems of State Government Revenue from marketing board crops, the relevant concept for most of the crops is the price elasticity of sales to the marketing board. Some illustrative calcu- lations are carried out to show the dependence of govern— ment revenue from marketing board crops on this parameter and the level of taxes. Chapter V presents some empirical eVidence on the sales elasticity parameter and other panmeters and other effects of government pricing policy. ‘11 examines t': a “gin-a . galizers of state "fir.“ngs, draws . n... I a 2:221:25 for agric; 19 Chapter VI examines the potential of marketing boards as stabilizers of state revenues. Chapter VII summarizes the main findings, draws some conclusions and offers recom- mendations for agricultural development in Nigeria in the 1970's and 1980's. 2..._ ...e count I; 11570, b}: 270 mil‘ ezzzazge earnings a" .09, 58 per cent l.’ i3. 1: . . '1 n < 7‘ 'l 3-H»; man R..." n . Ridden; "oi-Jada“ Spinning a :rtgof bales of cc fate: use was 115.2 treasury-over sto 3113? Green on Catt finest of Agric ‘ 3Glenn L. -'~~..ach t ‘ FOOTNOTES 1Second National Development Plan, 1970-74 (Lagos: Federal Ministry of Information, 1970), p. 53. 2The country's revenue from oil was EN 80 million in 1970, EN 270 million in 1971; the share of foreign exchange earnings accounted for by oil was 41 per cent in 1969, 58 per cent in 1970, and 71 per cent in 1971. See New Nigerian (Kaduna, February 26, 1972), p. 1. Whereas Nigerian spinning accounted for only 8.6 per cent of total crop of bales of cotton in 1960-61, by 1970-71, the esti- mated use was 115.2 per cent, with the shortage to be met from carry-over stocks from 1969-70. See Report of the Study Group on Cotton and Other Fibres (Lagos: Federal Department of Agriculture, 1971), p. 14 3Glenn L. Johnson, et al., A Generalized Simulation Approach to Agricultural Sector Analysis With Special A i cation to Ni eria (East Lansing: Michigan State UniverSity, 19715, p. 12 4Report of the Study Group on Oil Palms (Lagos: Federal Department of Agriculture, June, 197ITT p. 33. 5See P. T. Bauer, West African Trade (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), pp. 263-75; P. T. Bauer and B. 5. Yamey, Markets, Market Control and Marketing Reform (weidenfeid and—Nicolson, 1968)? pp. 133-55. 6P. T. Bauer, West African Trade, p. 268. 71bid., p. 276. Ma 8First Annual Re ort of the Nigerian Groundnut -—£§§ting Board, p. 16. 20 9 Develo ment ”.4" Elgerla. all". 243. 12 .' ”The Cocoa v establis‘ment of the .3211" 3*. world *9 :2: will be les; 2:: eassa es. “he a 'sxp‘..s.' There ‘ 22.22. the average we Erziazers. On these ‘ which will t '11-;33 Of high we- ‘2rzfits‘ will be 2.: 3%“- 8953539018 st-< grzixer. Thus, or. ingested t)“ at tt. 5‘3 Sws antial 31.12911 0:} “0:1 6 YT -:i1‘ri2tra Battier. .. LS Significant t 7 'suulas" adtd “lbs . H V‘ “ES 9v us. {Ly ‘V‘ ‘U ‘ \ I- . “1 Cf “h 2" 3% L~Cr . n o‘ \ -A “‘s'j" a ls E . 4“»er1 - ~25- “ 1‘ ‘-de;“ L *‘ I \. n~ 21 9Developmgpt Plan 1962-68 (Kaduna: Government of Northern Nigeria, Ministry “I“? U r1 > P r yr Yr which leads to more of Yj being produced than would have been the case in the absence of taxation, and vice versa for “j < ur. In Southern Katsina and Northern Zaria and parts of North East and North West States where it is possible to grow either cotton or groundnuts with the same fixed resources at the beginning of each growing season, differ- ential taxation which renders “j ¢ ur induces substitution in production which leads to the production of relative amounts of cotton and groundnuts different from what they would have been in the absence of these taxes. Table 3.1 shows empirical evidence of induced allocative distortions in the relative amounts of cotton and groundnuts produced in the Northern States, particularly in North Central, North West, and North East States, given the specifications of our model. All other things equal, government and marketing board taxation of groundnuts had the effect of inducing production of groundnuts at a level lower than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes in 10 out of 16 years and of inducing production on a larger scale than would have been the case in 6 out of 16 years. Taxation of cotton had the effect of inducing production of cotton HUI!) ‘illlilulll‘ XEF kahuna—«CHE ...,! CA..~\\2£ .Uth .0 w ICQEOU u :2 H EOE... ‘EL. Ibuhk H: his—av... rm .0 « IEEOU BIDS—Icha- HIuUCOoH.“ 092 fi: EDD-.13.:- nIu .u...au3p~ IUICCCDOEO 1 Ii leaaou o‘.‘..b?.2 ~|Ehlh I‘u‘gl. .1... EIQL. .66su~ 12mm. n Ibrvikkufill Phul'PnJLl P- . . . :1- 3 Fu-r-Jfiu.eia- Ibno.-Fsru3.uh° “a..- :3d.«n.»V Lav I'rvu.hnn -51d'd-‘ in» I"§.F Fw.h|n..n- DC‘UEXH'! menu- UKE-hkpu>°fiv Nae 40 .muooa uauauo onu who: moon» on unommam H50 now ouoa escape» a no: ma onuhwma name no >uw~anuaam>ocoz .cou won xuu ouamomaoo «can oowum mono uoc aw oowum uoosvoua Huwucouom «ouoz .neuuu «madam cuonuuoz co moosooum auscocdoum can couuoo no mowufiucusw o>fiucaou on» c« ncofluuoumao 0>aumooHHo on on peso: upon» can A n u:\ a + H I u: I : .omouo moon» no cuon co moxou oc nu“: “uncanny kn oo>wooou maausuou um3 unsu couuou uou ouaua uouscoum Hoaucouom awed mo scauuomoum on» ma una .nuceuam ha vo>wmomu haacsuoc on: uonu muscpcdoum you oowum umoacoua Hoaucmuom awed mo cowuuomoum on» mg and Hugo .mo £8338 .m .o .HmnommH couuooimco «muomma nuacocsoum uou mmmmmmw xaa ..ewnu .Go-~mma coupon uou nouamau gearuhh..m ..omma. .a nmzmo O .uaumwfiz cfl mcfiuwxuoz couuo now mousmwm xoe ~ U .Hmowfiux .z .wolmmmH ..uwu . .uocaoawmm .x .o .~mnommH mouaua couuou “.oanu .mounmoa nunnuasouo nacho uo mcauoxuox .Homuauz .m .owammaa .‘unuHH nanny .mmma .nazuu .uwuomwz ca £u3ouu oHEocoom can accecuo>00 oucuasofiu 4 acumoom .uoconaum .& .U .leomma noowum vacdcdouo uom «oouaom Aha. Hem. mm.vm a.» m~.hv mmh. m.hn m.m m.o~ mead ooa. com. ~o.wm «.HH ~a.vv as». m.mm m.a ..an voaa sea. we». mn.am a.w as... Hma. ~.vn a.» m.o~ noaa mom. eds. uq.vm n.v mp.a. use. n.5n ..G a.~m «was «mm. ama. «uh.mm woo. oe.mm Haw. ¢.oe o.v o.mm Home nan. oqo.a sm.nm o.~u ha.mm vac. «.vc «.a o.on coma Ham. omo.~ pv.~m G.~- so.mm mam. m.sn o.~ p.vn amma mo.H ooo.a mm.vm .o.- Hm.vm ova.“ m.mm F.H- c.6n amma omo. was. om.mw H..H oo.vm Ham. m.a. o.ma n.nn smog mo.” no». m~.~h H.AH ma.mm com. ¢.nv o.o «.mm umaa em.” mew. mo.am o.p~ om.vm Hm». G.mn a.m p.mn mama ham. vow. Hm.ah n..~ oa.mm «mo. o.mm n.oH “.mn emu” GH.H mmm. HH.mm m.mv Hm..m sac. a.om ~.o~ a.on «mad mac.a Ame. em.cw m.o~ so.mm mas. n.om n..a o.on «man mo~.a mmm. HH.~HH qo.mm po.mm mew. n.mm n.p~ o.on Hmaa as». New. hp.~s so.mm sn.on Ame. o.~v o.m« «.Hu cam" :oa\zm nos\za a: u sedan ads ocuum n ocuum Ida oowum H1. : Monsooum ova-oaaoo nooavoum a : noosooum ouaoomaoo noosvoum uoo» : n adducouom uoz Monacouom uoz couuoo nuscccsouu .moma-omoa .aaummaz .nauau nouaum cuonuuoz :0 couscoum nuacvanouu can couuou no nonuum o>duuaom co «ouch canon ucwuoxun! can ucoaduo>oo no uuoouunll.a.n uqnda g; a smaller scale absence of these t reduction on a 1" o i: the absence of ritpctential pr sanity. The at M ..tton-groundnuts grcrdnuts induc focd crops than \ these taxes for ' are affected 5; reSpect to food Some ii“ by He) should at a. other crops ind the quanti remain Constan 3 n . ‘ v (n . . “‘0 Crop mixt t at ‘ 4 a~es' wit}. re: : - ”ins th. V. 41 on a smaller scale than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes in 6 out of 16 years and of inducing production on a larger scale than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes in 10 out of 16 years. Food crops are not taxed. Thus the proportion of unit potential producer price received by food crop growers is unity. The above model therefore implies that in the cotton-groundnuts-food crops zone, taxation of cotton and groundnuts induced farmers to produce relatively more of food crops than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes for most of the period concerned. This must have affected specialization patterns in the country with respect to food production. Some limitations of the special.case represented by (4e) should be noted. The assumption that the quantities of other crops other than the two crops under consideration and the quantities of inputs used in a given crop season remain constant may be particularly restricting where in a given crop season farmers grow more than two crops whose quantities change during a given crop season. However, two crop mixtures are common throughout the Northern States,4 with quantities in the input vector more or less remaining the same in a given crop year. In such instances, the model does approximate reality. The above analysis, therefore, provides strong reasons to expect allocative distortions induced by serpent and mar is relative amour minced in the Ni Implicit glared relative matted values c grices. It is e: influenced not 0. treats of these if these prices. AI . " a given Cr0p we mOdel rep {Mr av ‘, . 9.5101]. the S ha.“ . u CIOPS. In need not hold . E1 hp t xa & ~11. i? ‘ F Y 42 government and marketing board taxation with respect to the relative amounts of cotton, groundnuts, and food crops produced in the Northern States (1950-65). Implicit in the model is the assumption that the planned relative outputs of crops are functions of the expected values of the probability distributions of crop prices. It is eminently plausible that farmers are influenced not only by mean prices, but also by higher moments of these distributions--particularly the variances of these prices.5 Insofar as farmers are risk averse,6 we would expect that the elasticity of the planned output of a given crop with respect to the standard deviation of the price of this crop is negative. In this sense, the above model represents the special case when this is zero for each crop or one in which,in the presence of risk aversion, the standard deviations are the same for the two crops. In the more general case, these conditions need not hold. In addition, other variables like weather, amount of information possessed by farmers, etc., that also influence farmers' decisions have not been treated. Effects of Taxes and Subsidies on Equilibrium Amounts of Resources Used From (4d), for the ith input and the jth crop: A.p 1 x a -F . BY. 1 _ m+i _ . 3;;T——--. Fj — Sii.' from which eating that an i. Librim be demand: value product of verzlcsive of qov 1:35 the subs idyl ti one minus the v Oh :‘ -Ibcd' y r:- _ 1 "fix. ‘ — T—-. P‘ 1'13 U- . LJ : “ We ‘ e 2?- a‘J‘Pgh “;‘Hts I ,"A ’ U v‘lerp" 43 3Y0 A. i = 1' 0.0, n I 1 Yj xi "j “la j = 1, ..., m meaning that an input will, in profit maximizing equi- librium be demanded up to the point where the marginal value product of the input equals its acquisition price (exclusive of government subsidy) times the ratio of one th minus the subsidy rate per unit of the i input divided by one minus the tax rate on the jth crop. In equilibrium then, 1i i = l, ..., n xi'Yj “j xia j = 1, ..., m from which it follows that: A. A. . 1 > 1) 1:1 n MVP =-—P =P as—=l ’ "" (Sb) xin “j xia < xia ”j < j = 1, ..., m where A. is the proportion of market unit acquisition 1 price of the ith input paid by the farmer and “j is the proportion of the unit potential producer price of the jth crop received by the farmer. This means that for given subsidy rates on other inputs, quantities of other inputs and product price, if the proportion of unit price of, say, fertilizers in groundnuts production paid by farmers exceeds the proportion of market unit price of groundnuts received by the farmer, then as a result of government policy, the farmer is being induced to use less 2a: the equil ibri 2e obtained in t :‘32 tax rate per 1 equivalent form o: "wits taken subsidy rate per Earner would be i fiend the same braid have demant arlreting board . 355ertilizers e the farmer WOUh more than the e will have beEr fixation . Before :0 EXtEnd the ‘n"’95tment in be neither in "mile thei taut .' Lon arid 44 than the equilibrium amounts of fertilizers that would have obtained in the absence of government policies. If the tax rate per unit of groundnuts (expressed in the equivalent form of the proportion of the unit price of groundnuts taken away by the government) equals the subsidy rate per unit of fertilizers,then the groundnut farmer would be induced under our stated conditions to demand the same equilibrium amount of fertilizers that he would have demanded in the absence of government and marketing board policies. If the subsidy rate per unit of fertilizers exceeds the tax rate per unit of groundnuts, the farmer would be induced by government policy to employ more than the equilibrium amounts of fertilizers that would have been employed in the absence of government taxation. Before presenting the empirical evidence, we need to extend the model to take account of salvaging and dis- investment in resources and the possiblity that there may be neither investment nor disinvestment as farmers re- organize their farms in response to marketing board taxation and subsidy policies. In response to changes in the rates of taxes on marketing board crops and subsidies on inputs, farmers are induced to reorganize their farms. This reorganization nay lead to the salvaging of and disinvestment in certain inputs; it may lead to purchases and investments in new 132325 or it may t‘r- ..g crops on . 51:2.) opportunit‘J reorganizing the or marketing boa; {Ere uj is the ,::;ce of the ma. is the Polite: ‘3 up,“ 0 .Uk” Y). and Y- in 'th ' ‘3 CrOp' re L." i #- .J S the amOu: ~:‘ :‘3e 7 “1' 0n )- .. . ‘atgd. Le ”he i L ' “dch Says :13 ‘ is ' lts mar‘KEt 45 inputs or it may lead to a reallocation of a fixed quantity among crops on the basis of an internal (within the farm- firm) opportunity cost principle. The gain (G) from reorganizing the farm-firm in response to changes in taxes on marketing board crops and subsidies on inputs is:7 c = ? u.p (y. — ij) - r ai(Xi. - x10) (6) j=1 3 Yj 3 J 3 where “j is the proportion of the unit potential producer price of the marketing board crop received by the farmer, Py. is the potential producer price of the marketing board crgp, on and Yj are the initial and reorganized output of h the jt crop, respectively, ai is the unit value of Xi' Xij is the amount of X1 used in producing the jth crop after reorganization and XiO is the initial quantity of Xi on hand. Let us define three price equations for Xi: one which says if the reorganized quantity exceeds the initial quantity on hand, then the relevant price for X1 is its market acquisition price times one minus the subsidy rate per unit of Xi; if the reorganized quantity of Xi is less than the initial quantity on hand, then the relevant price for X1 is the market salvage price; and, if after profit maximizing reorganization it does not pay to vary the quantity of Xi, then Xi is fixed and the relevent price for Xi is its on-farm opportunity cost. ThUSI m > if 2 ij 1‘1 ,. g: ._ ( X.“ A. l] l - if Zx-- = X here? is th x.s if ancunt of X ire farm-firm w: these restrictit 46 Thus, “‘ o if 2 xi. > Xi , then ai = AlPX a , j=1 3 i if 2X.. < X.0 then a. = P . 13 i ' i x.s ' j 1 - _ O .= and if inj — Xi , then Pxis < ai < Aipxia' i 1,...,n. where Px s is the salvage value of the 1th input. Let i Wi = amount of Xi purchased and Vi = amount of Xi sold. The farm-firm wishes to maximize (G) above subject to these restrictions: 2 x.. = x1 + wi - vi (6a) x. - V. 3'0 (6b) where (6a) says the reorganized quantity of inputs equals the initial quantity on hand plus new purchases less the quantity of inputs sold, while (6b) says sales of a given input cannot exceed initial quantity on hand. Form the Lagrangian: m 0 n n n O L a X u.P (Y. - Y. ) + X Px 1 — 2 lipx i Z 611[Xi - v1 m n O + wi - z xij] + z GZiIXi - Vi] (7) i=1 "*e Karin-Tucker c ‘ . and W. ar J are: . 3r. :- -13 —l—- - g'Y_W"‘y 8X Jx. J ‘- .. '3 a l) —: . - XP I ll 1 )1 l LII-:F - I _ i its 11 ' 0 ‘F‘=Xi - V. + .1 l ' O ‘gx - v > “‘e of the 151635 tt | 47 The Kuhn-Tucker conditions for maximizing with respect to x.., Vi and Wi and minimizing with respect to 61i and 621 1) are: BY 3L ' 3L Bxij - uij. 3X. - Gli E-O' 8X.. Xij - 0' Xij 2.0 3 (7a) 3 l 1) 3L 3L aw. ‘ 51. ' MP)... 5. 0' aw "i - 0: W1 1 0: (7b) J. 1. 1. 3L 3L 3V. 3 Px.s - éli - 621 5-0' 3v, Vi ' 0' Vi 3.03 (7C) 1 1 %_ ‘3 X.O " V. + W. - X X. . = 0 (7d) 11 i i 1 j 1] 3L a x O - v > 0 3L 6 = o 6 > 0 (7e) 8321 i i - ' 3321 21 ' 21 — ' (7a) states that in optimal reorganization of the farm- firm in response to taxes on marketing board crops and subsidies on inputs, the marginal value product of the input times the proportion of the unit potential producer price of the marketing board crop received by the farmer is less than or equal to its on-farm opportunity cost, 611. (7b) states that in equilibrium reorganization, the optimum purchases of Xi involve a net acquisition price (i.e., acquisition price inclusive of subsidies) equal to the on-farm opportunity cost of Xi' (7c) states that in equilibrium, the optimum sale of xi involves a salvage Value equal to the opportunity cost for Xi when less than 2;“! is sold. selling Xi 1 eguiiibriu'f. "" ‘i‘. 13., acqurs 12;? ) eq ‘. 'I ‘ = 3_ 2X w-P “94 J 3 h “r 4. a J f’A-I V" ' v nun-a finlcn «a V. “E n Prop“, “4. I. Q3“. H 48 xi0 is sold. In (7e), 621 turns out to be the gain from selling Xi rather than using it, while (7d) says that in equilibrium, the constraint in (6a) is satisfied. From (7bh acquisition of Xi involves an acquisition price (AiPx a) equal to its on-farm opportunity cost in equi- i librium. Substituting this optimum equivalent of the opportunity cost in (7a), we get: BY. 31. _ _ 3L _ fit—7 ‘ “ij. nil.- AiPx.a 5- 0' B‘X‘T Xij ’ 0' Xij 10' (7a) 13 J 13 1 13 or BY. 1. 3L 1 8L ____ = p §_l_‘:_—— P , 5——— x.. =cL x..3_o (8) axij yj Xij uj xia Xij 1] 13 av. Xi from which P '5—1_ > P as -— > 1, where P is, in j xi- Xia ”j xia equilibrium, the on-farm opportunity cost of Xi' The on- farm opportunity cost is the relevant price for allocating a fixed amount of resources among competing crops. If there are neither sales nor acquisition of a given input after reorganization, from (7b) and (7c), the on-farm opportunity cost of the input will be between its acquisition price inclusive of subsidies and its salvage price. This on-farm opportunity cost of the input is its MVP evaluated at the crOp's potential producer price times the proportion of the unit potential producer price of the crop paid by the board to the farmers. Also 2151035 is '5 real price :2 past: a r 1:. taxes on I? 1;:reased in‘. 25.5 ch age J' tersely for a resources hat garticularly sztsidies on me wi .11 ma Ef'nornal“ fiePastures f hzmrs' inv exp-e St a re: Of IEHr ‘ 9 888 ' ~\l' response 5+1 49 Also important for investment-disinvestment decisions is the most recent history of relative prices. If real prices of resources have been persistently high in the past, a reduction in real prices through a reduction in taxes on marketing board crops may not result in increased investment in resources if farmers do not expect this change in marketing board policy to last, and con- versely for a sudden increase in taxes if real prices of resources had been persistently low in the past. This is particularly so for small changes in taxes on crops and subsidies on inputs. Farmers on the basis of past experi— ence with marketing board pricing policies form concepts of "normal" real prices for resources. Any sudden departures from these "normal" prices may not affect farmers' investment-disinvestment decisions if farmers expect a return to these "normal" prices. The importance of regressive expectations is thus emphasized in our response studies. Let there be a production function relating output of marketing board crop Y to inputs X1 and X2. Assume it does not pay to vary the quantity of X2 on hand, i.e., Px25 < uyPy gé; < A2px a for all possible changes in taxes on marketing board crops and all subsidies on the inputs (where ”y is the proportion of the unit potential producer price of Y received by the Ir —.{l"’ farm's and x2 31:8 Of X2 pai In Figu iii absence of ss-calied tradi tax, where all Talsrem equival (i.e., 55’ = r l :arrer to Chang ;;'.'en level of value, P b‘ x s' ‘ 1 Suppose a: . Jt x1 is EE". Elastity of X 3C"? "in iaeere is 5a" “aging of i: .:.e land and l 50 farmers and A2 is the proportion of the unit acquisition price of X2 paid by the farmer). In Figure 3.1, let EE by the MVP curve of X1 in the absence of taxes on Y. If the initial quantity of X1 on hand happens to be Kl,8 X1 is fixed in an economic sense. With the imposition of taxes on Y (marketing board so-called trading surpluses, produce sales tax and export tax, where all these taxes are converted into their ad valorem equivalents), the adjusted MVP is given by EE’ (i.e., EE’ = uyEE). With EE’, it still does not pay the farmer to change the level of X1 employed because at the given level of X1, its MVP is still higher than its salvage value, les’ but lower than its acquisition price, lea' Suppose taxes are raised so that the adjusted MVP of X1 is EE”. It pays to salvage some of the given quantity of X1 since its salvage value now exceeds its MVP. There is disinvestment by the amount KZKl' Such salvaging of inputs seems to have occurred withrespect to the land and labor resources employed on Northern States farms in recent years. If the initial quantity of X1 happens to be Ki, K3 is optimum quantity in the absence of taxes. With taxes leading to EE’, optimum amount of X1 is K3 implying that taxes have reduced acquisition in the optimum by K3K3. Taxes have thus reduced acquisitions of X 1 below what they would have been in the absence of taxes. With the heavier taxes leading to EE”, not only 51 / V TN K1 K1 “3 K3 K\ E “I" Figure 3.1 is the additional acquisition in the absence of taxes represented by KiK3 not forthcoming but also some of the initial quantity on hand (KZKI) is salvaged. The closer to the origin is the initial quantity on hand of X1, the more a given tax leads to less acquisitions of X1 than would have been the case in the absence of taxes. The movement of farm youth and school leavers from rural areas and non-use of available suitable land for cotton and groundnuts in the North-East, North-West and North-Central States are evidence of acquisitions that are less than would have been optimal in the absence of taxes. 1m In Figurt’ ratings given t‘. that the farmer where ll is the :5 X1 paid by t}.- facing the farm Whether or K3, with sub line, there wil Kim K; as the .: , - . .. SQbSIClles as in E / / [ '___ 52 In Figure 3.2, let EE, lea and les have the meanings given them above. Let the subsidy rate be t1 so that the farmer pays (1 - tl)lea = lllea where A1 is the proportion of the unit acquisition price per unit of X1 of X1 paid by the farmer. The new supply curve of X 1 fac1ng the farmer is Alpx a' 1 Whether the initial quantity on hand is Kl'9 Ki or K3, with subsidies leading to AlPx a as the new supply 1 line, there will be additional acquisition of X1 up to K4. With Ki’ as the initial quantity on hand, the same amount of subsidies do not lead to new acquisitions of XI. in E‘\ (ha r\\\\ AJ§A l I l i I l l i K3 i £5. p< K" :K‘KqK? E Figure 3.2 The case 1‘; will be brief 2 ’lea' le): ratings. If t” aftaxes on Y 1i stillead to he czher hand, wit; sate amount of evacguisitior. cse,a resourdI Variable as a J Effie initial 3 _--—-.—— "E 14 l 53 The case of simultaneously taxing Y and subsidizing x1 will be briefly presented. In Figure 3.3, EE, EE’, EE”, lea' lllea and les all have their previous meanings. If the initial quantity on hand is K3, imposition of taxes on Y leading to EE” and the granting of subsidies on Xl lead to neither acquisition nor sale of X1. On the other hand, with initial quantity of XI of K1 and with the same amount of subsidies and taxes leading to EE’ there is new acquisition up to the new equilibrium point Ki; in this case, a resource that was initially fixed now becomes variable as a result of taxes on Y and subsidies on X1. ” If the initial quantity on hand is Kl , then taxes \ \ \I ;\l\\ \ ~ 1.3m ["3 / / I 1 K5 “3 KI K: 2»: Figure 3.3 ref-resented by E: lead to acquiSit' represented W E sitions of X1 in , .I From F19 fcllcwing propor' szbsidies, if t: given w...mic sense , seed to be subs to occur. For the differentia :ze larger the I.“ n .. occur and c{ | niti .al guanti ‘iill‘ure 3.1) I “I99 taxes Is a 91Ven dif fe] 54 represented by EE’ and subsidies represented by Alpxla lead to acquisitions by the amount of Ki’Ki; with taxes represented by EE” and with the same subsidies, acqui- sitions of XI increase by the amount Ki’Ks. From Figure 3.1 and the accompanying analysis, the following propositions can be derived. In the absence of subsidies, if the resource was initially fixed in an economic sense, taxes on the marketing board crop would need to be substantial for salvaging (and disinvestment) to occur. For this initially fixed resource, the larger the differential between salvage and acquisition values, the larger the required taxes on the crop for disinvestment to occur and conversely for a small differential. If the initial quantity on hand were the equilibrium amount K3 (Figure 3.1), small taxes leave the resource fixed while large taxes lead to some salvaging and disinvestment, for a given differential between salvage and acquisition values. If the initial quantity on hand in the absence of taxes is less than the equilibrium amount K3, small taxes lead to acquisitions that are less than would have been the case in the absence of taxes while large taxes lead to pppp_reduced acquisitions as well as some salvaging of the initial quantity on hand. Apart from the basic result of resource fixity, other results are obtained that are different from those of the neoclassical theory of the firm when the assumption of equality between salvage and 3""'Sltl0n value ‘. not -‘ r catand of K3 (Fl :rearcts a reduc. :axes, the exter. resource enployr salvaging up to eg;als MVP (e.g '33 in Figure 35319 large th6 tie is the d; between lea a: an initial qua. that adjust BE vertiCal line Elf-Ended me “ilisitions l taxes. For 1- ‘4 Figure 3.1). ‘ '0»... ““u' Simi] mi 3.3 bUt V saith prOduCJ | :::#‘lp .u.& have Pht. I -: er . i EigCeS ‘ 55 acquisition values is dropped. With an initial quantity on hand of K3 (Figure 3.1), whereas the neoclassical theory predicts a reduced use of the resource as a result of taxes, the extended theory predicts that small taxes leave resource employment unaffected while large taxes lead to salvaging up to the equilibrium point where salvage value equals MVP (e.g., K2K3 is salvaged with taxes leading to EE” in Figure 3.1). The corresponding salvaging for the same large taxes ('EE”') using the usual neoclassical model is the distance between K3 and the intersection between P 10 With an initial quantity on hand of Ki (Figure 3.1), for taxes and EE”, which is many times K2K3. that adjust EE down up to the intersection of lea and the vertical line at Ki, both the neoclassical theory and its extended form produce the same result--taxes reduce acquisitions of x1 below optimal levels in the absence of taxes. For larger taxes (as represented by EE” in Figure 3.1), the neoclassical theory predicts disposals or reductions in quantity on hand that are much larger than those predicted with the extended theory. Similar propositions can be drawn from Figures 3.2 and 3.3 but we leave these out because labor and land which produce the bulk of value added in Nigerian agri- culture have not been subsidized significantly in the past. Some clarifications are necessary for drawing inferences from available empirical evidence. From (5b), marginal va exceeds the acq ratio of the p! the farmer to 1 price of the C1 :rthis case, t induce farmers been the case onverse resul Equilibrium us 1'? equals its fixed resource 2;;ortunity cc 356). When t Ilfferential P~' a? .0 of the input . - Held by 56 the marginal value product of a resource from a given crop 11 of the resource if the exceeds the acquisition price ratio of the proportion of unit acquisition price paid by the farmer to the proportion of the unit potential producer price of the crop received by the farmer exceeds unity. In this case, government and marketing board policies will induce farmers to use less of the resource than would have been the case in the absence of taxes and subsidies. The converse result holds when this ratio is less than unity. Equilibrium use of a resource here is defined as when its MVP equals its acquisition price which in the case of a fixed resource allocated to two crops is the foregone opportunity cost (i.e., its foregone MVP in alternative use). When the model is extended to take account of the differential between salvage and acquisition values, a ratio of the proportion of unit acquisition price of the input paid by the farmer to the proportion of unit potential producer price of the crop paid by the board to the farmer greater thanunity also implies that less of the resource is being used than would have been the 12 In this case, case in the absence of these policies. however, "less use" includes both the acquisitions that are less than would have otherwise been the case in the absence of these policies as well as the induced salvaging and disinvestment in the quantity on hand as the salvage value of the res result of these relevant acquis: is the on-farm < ressurces that erztezc'ed model, :‘isinvestment. this resource fl 1:.tersection p5 Tables . - ’i? "“59th boar aid and labor £111 ‘1‘ C051”- of l“. ::fi§1 ““‘Y labor ( aerxet aCQUis: “f resOurces) ngrnmeht ar. P'l & C65; C)f Cyt}: n, . 53ch Ct priCel sEQfi . u: t111:e(i :1- "4-48 in the _| SCEE as salvfl ‘V ltiOns wt :52“ ' palm .533: ( 57 value of the resource relative to its MVP rises as a result of these taxes. For resources that are fixed, the relevant acquisition price for allocating between crops is the on-farm opportunity cost of the resource. For resources that were initially fixed (economically) in the extended model, large taxes would lead to salvaging and disinvestment. Even small taxes lead to disinvestment in this resource the nearer the initial quantity is to the intersection point between the BE and les curves. Tables 3.2 and 3.3 show the effects of taxes on marketing board crops on the real (relative) prices of land and labor employed on cotton and groundnuts farms in the Northern States, 1950-66. So long as farmers pay the full cost of hired labor or bear the full real costs of family labor (where these costs may be represented by the market acquisition prices or the on-farm opportunity costs of resources), i.e., xi = 1, then for any crop subject to government and marketing board taxation and for given prices of other inputs, quantities of other inputs, and product price, farmers would, in equilibrium, be demanding less hired labor and/or family labor than they would have done in the absence of government taxation, or salvaging some as salvage values exceed MVPS. Under our stated conditions, this means that for cotton, groundnuts, soy- beans, palm oil and beniseed in the Northern States less labor (family and hired) is being used than would have I l “I. D . \Ft\l ' v.5 U _ ...L mr.3 «G .wb «23 ~ SCH. CU « ML LEUSfiOHfl Cf..r>‘ ‘1 Cu WJHQMJW EQ*L:C ~f¢€$ U “549%va xcE OUDUOha ozu a 32a 1 utfirb . _ . 0 Ca Lbbfimaolufi afldUCWUCL ..u ‘ .-N K ~r.« UCSuCL CCdU..QLChl m. MC CCthOQ XEL. ACUrvL. lryh; u fl: Inglis I .....a..—|A...s.a~ ‘su— ~r..:J‘z \u.::.-...~ rise-.03. .~,~...~.u.~..z .~go ltL-.-.~..-:.-v .hn. ~mro‘...~. s... n~.o.4.-s ~.~ l...lc. ~oh.~a\~ .' ll I II. I Nu-nnt In..—l.u.- .111». . . (3.3.. F‘s-l... 1‘... :li.4¢ I‘- A-u). au. 5.0:» «u...»- 58 .uoan cam Gama nuon mom wuwcd mamswo .mHmEhmm mn cwmm mUHSOmmu may no mowum coflufimwswom used map mo cofluuomoum on» .H& umcu 0m vmuflpflmndm no: mums Honda can bend umnu omesmmm ma uHm .waanHm>m mousmwm xmu Hmuou waco .NmIOmmH Mom .uau .mo .uocflwaamm .M .w mom .NmuommH wousmwm xmu can mdUaHQ mom .mm .m .ma QmZmU .mHHmMaz cfl muscocsouu molmwflumxumz one .Homwflux .m mom .omnmmma mwusmflm xmu cam mmoflum mom “mouaom hm.H mmh. mHN. m.H H.H ¢.m Hmm.¢ moma hm.H own. «Hm. m.a ~.H m.m mom.v coma o~.H 0mm. ova. m.H mo. b.v omb.m mama mH.H mum. FNH. m.a v.m| v.m mmn.m moma vH.H mum. mud. o.H ~.~u H.o mmo.m Homa ~m.a 0mm. oma. o.H N.H m.m omo.~ coma wo.H mmm. «no. o.H m.m| m.m NH¢.m mmma mm. mmo.a mm0.I o.H m.n| m.m 5mm.~ mmma mv.a mow. 5mm. o.H w.h N.h mmo.~ hmma >~.H can. cam. o.H ¢.H N.m NmH.m mmma 5H.H 5mm. mva. o.a «.mn .m.c mwm.~ mmma m¢.a mmo. mam. o.H ~.m .m.c om¢.m vmma >m.a mmm. mom. .m.c Ha .m.c mom.m mmma ov.H man. mam. .m.c .m.c .m.c .m.c «mma mv.H who. mmm. .m.c .m.c .m.c .m.c Hmma m¢.~ Hmv. mom. .m.c .m.c .m.: .m.c omma zm ooo. 2m muoeumm ou xme commcousm oommzousm cos you couscousm mofiuso Mum» n oflmm mmz mo o>flwsH0cH cos you oumom mcaumxumz cos uom uuomxm .1 page ooflum mowum noosooum xma moanoum map 0» msHQHSm moauso Hmuoe dMl noosooum Hmwucmuom mo uuomxm K Hmfiucouom cowuuomoum mm mo c0wuuom xma Hmuoe loam an: .mwmauomma .mauomwz .meumm mmumum cumsuuoz ll: :0 coonmEm uonmq can pang mo mooflum Ao>flumammv Hmmm no muscocsouu co mmxme mo muommwman.~.m ma m5. l n 1 d . cm... a 110th. a It’s-ch 34 with ll) «I5 09‘s.; uOUSHXF-B .I. 2.156.. u: C°<.ou.:—:.-E .«1 ~': hI-Iql sIln'K .Ionubn- Ififlh. .. In- 1“ Inc—.95. Ha gulq.~.J=H '2tu h..:.ul»nfi ~de—.S.~..L LC Cayudhanruu~53 I‘ IIL. u'GCL. ...l.‘ thus! ’2. P..>-~.~Er— uni-..- CCF ..OA It... [a — I.!nI-C.» pup-C Fun-Id h an ..U— I..- 32. :3. :t I: a EU Isfahan» A.)1d'~.~hw ‘1'! s Sun ..JL nhAu «Que: IIII... M: Iablhulaa4... I452. .uonua can undo auoa no oases gangs. .Holudu on... an coda coupon...— 23 no nova gwuouqsvoa you: no gouuonoua 05 .«x 0.5 on conga-n5. you on: hon-H can and." unnu vol»:- 3 and 22.005” «0 0-93 on 3 can: on.) «7.33 uou 3:303 33) .00 .m _. . . gum 05 no aha-8 26‘- 05 ha 3:32. coca Iouu 2.333 393 ucououuad guano uou .05.?! .n .m 72.3 .305 Juana—.633 «0 9338 Haven.— 303.3380 uaoaoodo>oa onusuaaoouoz aaaoouaz no. .Houoooo aoauoo no nouauo uauuoouav no noooum no» .oonoo .oo ..Hsoa .aauaoo canon oaauoxuux any so oocouooaoo 30.33535” “g. MHHZ .6958 8- 356505 «0 «037.3: and How was can: 0.30080 33 5 2.0.39.3 on. gun. on» no m ¢ Jim i .t and {0.393. .0 .x o: .oonomoa couuoo uo non-am 05333 new as» can: ousnoum no 90309000 usuua «83» was won .mm .m 23 330th .3 oo- Jbloooa can: 03.3 23 you 3:32. uom .3230. «.3033. 05 no 2:803 2830.3 >5: 5.“: uouon no None.“ 0383!. 1 930259300 $2530: .308 oauuoao co nouns counoog: a can: ans.» oau “on you nooouo couuoo H ovouu once can: Aos-vsv .oo. «.muda conga ..uoaaoadom .uoauoa ousu-ouu nus: noouu-u Iguana-«u h! luau wanna-cu noon: 305.3300 56 a! and sauna Bacon—noun «duufiuom on» you 3 6023 and scuba» ova-0900 on» noun: 3 gloom." coon.- ouuum SE. .2 .m .3 9:80 .3 run-ooh. .3 .3qu- Houoqux vows and moo—vacuum ”anions uou noon: Ova—um 39.58 549 oa.~ poo. no“. o.~u p.o~oa- v.0oa o.ooo wood as.” omo. ova. o.» o.«- H.~oa o.¢oo mood ou.~ woo. «on. «.HA m.oov H.~o~ o.n~o «cod oa.a poo. no”. o.o v.oou H.oon v.o~o noon o~.~ moo. moo. o.v o.ovon o.o- v.uno «no» co.” ooo.~ coo. voo.ou n.oo~au H.~au o.oooa Hood mo. "no.” sno.- 0.“- v.ooou o.vo H.nno oooa no. one.” coo.- 0.“- «.voouc n.ao o.ono oooa co.” ooo.~ Hoo.u oo.o. o.o~o«- o.oaa ~.Hoo anon on.» ooh. van. fl.oH v.ooa a.oo o coo soon ~o.- nor. an". a.p~ o.oov v.oo a «do wood ov.a ooo. Hon. o.o~ o.nooa H.«o o coo mood vo.a coo con. o.vu o.ooo~ .a.n a mop vooa on.a ooo. How. o.nv o.~oo~ .a.a « «do moo” on.“ How. ova. m.o« n.ooaa .¢.a o our «mod on.” ooo. How. oo.on o.ooo« .a a non Hood ow.“ «no. non. vo.oo v.~o- a a u.a ooou 2a coo. so nun-nan 0» nouns acoanouso ounce nos ..«uan an.» on: uoao up: can» no o>ausaoau :99 non nae oaauoxunz ousuouo vacuum .I: ooouo nauseouo guano nauseouo cannon-cu on» on «quay ox unauauuoo no unannouoa no undouso guoaoum . n: cofltoaoum on any annoy .ocodnoooa .qouooos .g-uuu oouuuu auoauuoz no vooonsa “and; can gang no cocoon “coouaaumo «ago no gouuoo no nanny no uuoouuuoo.n.n gangs rear. the case i: rates of utiliz explicitly intr production func now than would of taxation. E :2 work less i: fore in the ab fitted real c that are fully ;rices of othe :IGduce Price. u “H u ‘a I taxan WOu The f ‘~. a u “:34?“ "rtions 0 lane: (fami 1'] tie periOd we .axation polj “ taxeS o . .ixapton p01 "C J‘Vundn‘u‘ J. an LLA §~.:Sa ' c two r,— Jnl sh . '4 1:». “ice c fl "1114 60 been the case in the absence of taxation. Insofar as rates of utilization of family labor and hired labor are explicitly introduced as factors of production in the production function, labor is being used less intensively now than would have been most profitable in the absence of taxation. Farmers are being induced by taxes on crops to work less intensively than they would otherwise have done in the absence of these taxes. Insofar as there are imputed real costs (rents, customary dues, etc.) of land that are fully borne by farmers (Xi = 1), then for given prices of other inputs, quantities of other inputs and produce price, these taxes would induce the use of less land than would have been the case without them.13 The following conclusions may be drawn using the assumptions of the model. From Table 3.2, both land and labor (family and hired) used in groundnut production over the period were, on the whole, induced through government taxation policies to be employed on a smaller scale than the amounts that would have been employed in the absence of taxes on groundnuts. Government and marketing board taxation policies therefore have tended to limit the size of groundnut farms in the Northern States measured in terms of acreage or size of labor or intensity of use of these two resources. Only in one year (1958) was this taxation such as to induce farmers to use more labor and land than they would have done in the absence of taxes. Table 3 marketing board results are sir these taxes inc Lab: resource: Period, relati ergloyed in t‘n in two years cotton f arme r 61 Table 3.3 shows the effects of government and marketing board taxation on the resources in cotton. The results are similar to the groundnuts case: on the whole, these taxes induced the under-utilization of land and labor resources used in cotton production for most of the period, relative to the amounts that could have been employed in the absence of these taxation policies. Only in two years in Table 3.3 was taxation such as to induce cotton farmers to use more land and labor resources in cotton production than would have been consistent with profit maximization in the absence of these taxes. There was no year in groundnut production when labor and land resources were induced to be employed in the same amount as would have been done in the absence of government and marketing board taxation, i.e., there was no year in which taxation policy was neutral with respect to the equili- brium amounts of land and labor that could have obtained in the absence of taxation. Only in two years (1958, 1961) was taxation neutral with respect to the equilibrium amounts of resource use in cotton. Our results on the allocative distortions of government and marketing board taxes with respect to resource use in the cotton and groundnut farms in the Northern States do approximate reality and have increased validity because only a very tiny proportion of these farmers use fertilizers and other inputs that are subsidized; her. and chemicals b iamers are cor. gractical purp:. ifgl-ortant poli sf this chapte Some 5 k I (D (1) ‘. )J to be n01 :ias Qfi Out e using a CObb— 7.22113 ..‘arianCe :f‘- o E of the ‘ :§ F.~“ ‘v \ .1 F, “I .. A‘N ‘N‘ ‘FE‘AQ_ 1“.t ‘J E‘ .1v-\ ‘1" ' Av- ‘ “is?” 62 subsidized; hence, any existing subsidies on fertilizers and chemicals become insignificant when the aggregate of farmers are considered and can thus be disregarded for all practical purposes. As a practical matter therefore, there have been no compensating subsidies in the past on any significant scale, though this could become an important policy variable in the future (see last section of this chapter). Elasticities and Their Limitations Some serious limitations of elasticity concepts need to be noted before we illustrate the nature of the bias of our estimates of effects of government policies using a Cobb-Douglas function. Samuelson14 has listed the noninvariance of elasticities to changes in origin and our failure to treat the variable of interest directly as some of the problems. Thus, the price elasticity of demand for a product may be of some use in examining the qualitative behavior of revenue, but then this is due to our failure to examine the behavior of total revenue directly. Glenn Johnson15 has provided theoretical reasons why elasticity concepts may not be very useful. He has shown by implication that the percentage change in a dependent variable for a one per cent change in an explanatory variable is not invariant with respect to the traction and grevious histo 15:3.” variabl :etween its 55 are held wi th ::e future, t} :15 asset. Let s tiiit salvage graduct price 'C"n “°‘~~lrces 5'11. - 35’) “‘3 va- g “mes.” ir 33.-n wQPts C Pres H 63 direction and size of the change; to this we add the previous history of changes or movements in the expla- natory variable. When MVP's of a durable input are between its salvage and acquisition values and expectations are held with certainty that these bounds would hold in the future, then it does not pay to invest or disinvest in this asset. Let some durable inputs have their MVP's between their salvage values and their acquisition prices. Let product price history be such that in the opinions of farmers crop price has been unusually low and they expect a return to more "normal" prices in near future. If farmers have regressive expectations, then they would invest in additional resources even though calculations using (current) actual product price will indicate that it does not pay to invest or disinvest in additional resources. The same considerations will apply in our analysis of disinvestment in productive assets. All this calls for caution in our response studies; it is a cry for modesty in our claims for the usefulness of elasticity concepts. Comparative Statics and Biases in Our Estimate of'Effects 0f_§overnment and Marketinngoard Taxation and Subsidies on Resource Use One important use of comparative statics is to predict the response of the dependent variable (direction 335 magnitude) of analysis is ire response of resources to g: :ax rates on c: at their rest. The na government pri F - :....5T.d curve f Ll; 191i constant 513* E“.t1y S t E 64 and magnitude) for given parametric changes. A framework of analysis is potentially more useful if it can predict the response of equilibrium amounts of land and labor resources to given changes in subsidy rates on inputs and tax rates on crops that are imposed by State Governments and their respective marketing boards. The nature of the bias in estimates of effects of government pricing policies using the MVP curve as the demand curve for the resource needs to be ascertained. In the agricultural economics literature, what is being held constant has sometimes not been clearly and con- sistently stated.16 The Bias in Estimates of Effects of Government_and Marketing Board Taxation of Crops and Subsidies on Inputs on Resource Use Using a Copy-Douglas Production Function17 With the imposition of government and marketing board taxes on a crop and a subsidy on an input used to produce a crop, then for given prices of other crops and other inputs, whether use of the subsidized input will increase, remain the same or decrease depends on whether the percentage fall in the net acquisition price of the input times its own price elasticity of demand exceeds, equals or is less than the absolute value of the percentage fall in net producer crop price times the elasticity of demand for the input with respect to net producer crop _ _.,-.L :rice.18 Estirr rescurce use de resource use a board pricing 7‘ ‘_ ‘ vial. l 3 35-"? curve a '11 N (X .L 65 18 Estimates of induced percentage changes in price. resource use depend on these elasticities and the magni— tudes of the tax and the subsidy. Any bias in any of the elasticities would bias estimates of percentage changes in resource use as a result of government and marketing board pricing policies. What is the nature of the elasticity bias in using an MVP curve as the recource demand curve instead of the "true"19 demand curve? Let the Cobb-Douglas form be: <1 , Bi > O (i = 1,2), (7) from which the profits (N) are defined as: B B 1x Z-Ap 2 l xla TT=IJPAX y y 1 X - A P X2 (7') Solving the necessary conditions for profit maximization simultaneously for X1 and X2, we get, in the case of X1, its true demand function to be 8 + -1 B 2 [(81+82) u PYAB2 B -__1_ B 2 1 1.xla Y l 2)!& a demand function that is linear in the logs of the price variables. P P and Px are the market prices for y' xla 2a crOp Y and inputs X1 and X2 respectively in the absence of taxes and subsidies. From the above, the elasticity w. _--L I hum-n- I w ‘ " :f :enanc for 2. ire elasticity ‘ pr» ...p pIOC‘dCGI 66 of demand for X1 with respect to its net acquisition price (llPx a) is: l n = <0; Xl'(Allea) 1+ 2 1 the elasticity of demand for X1 with respect to the net crop producer price (uyPy) is ”x (uP)='1'-'B'L-‘6“ ’0' l' y y l 2 Now suppose we solve for X1 and X2 not simultaneously but from each marginality (equilibrium) condition separately (which is what Heady and Ulveling have done in their analysis of leasing rights), then the demand function for X1 which is defined for given quantities of X2 is 1 1 31.x 82 _ 61‘1 . x1 = (Alpxla) [uyPyBle2 1 (7a) from which these elasticities (whose meanings are clear from the subscripts) are derived: , 1 xl'(Allea) B1 1 n, =—l—)O' from which I I I "Xult’lpx a) * l implies elasticity of :Ef-farn acqui ;C'.'err.r:ent an: extension ser' when we use a, true dehand C Very m curve was not only ess e; 5133 be dete . is also mpg. .ntuiti'lely stitching to al. a.30 the imp «1. ...e C5139 .or Catmgt e163: ltles Of ‘1 e make Stat Easting t or the true 515‘Stlcit‘l be deeeh 67 B182 ) = xl'(AlPx1a) (n -n >0 which implies that there is a downward bias in the elasticity of demand for labor with respect to its net off-farm acquisition price (after deduction of such government and marketing board subsidies like free extension services, free adult education classes, etc.) when we use an MVP curve as a demand curve rather than the true demand curve.20 Very often we write and draw conclusions as if the MVP curve was the true demand curve for a resource. It is not only essential that the exact form of the elasticity bias be determined for different production functions; it is also important to determine on what its size depends. Intuitively it would appear that this bias will vary according to the importance of the input in production and also the importance of the other input. This indeed is the case for the Cobb-Douglas function. Larger values of 81 produce larger values of the bias; the smaller the output elasticity of the input, for given output elasti- cities of other inputs, the smaller the difference whether we make statements on the effects of government and marketing board prices using MVP curves as demand curves or the true demand functions. Similarly, the bias in the elasticity of demand with respect to produce price can be determined.21 Another II? of the inp and its market of demand for :arket acquisi failure to (iiS grices. This iisinvestment :arketing boa. intestment re raismg Of ma (f y (D 1:, rd 0 _ :‘japL‘ ‘ “isles re ““‘Ctiora, l 1332+ 68 Another important source of bias arises when the MVP of the input is between its off-farm acquisition price and its market salvage value. In this case the elasticity of demand for the input with respect to its off-farm market acquisition price is zero. This bias arises from .failure to distinguish between salvage and acquisition prices. This has implications for our predicted investment- disinvestment response to changes in the level of taxes on marketing board crops. Suppose we want to predict the investment response to a lowering of taxes, i.e., the raising of marketing board producer prices. In Figure 3.4, let the MVP of X with taxes at a given level be EE’. Let 1 taxes be reduced so that the MVP curve is EE. With initial quantities on hand of K1, or K3, both the neoclassical theory and its extension predict increased demand for X1 up to K3. However, through errors of organization, initial quantities may be K2. With the same amount of tax reduction, it does not pay the farm-firm to vary the quantity of X1 as its MVP is still between its off—farm market acquisition price and its salvage price. Thus, the neoclassical theory which assumes equality between the acquisition and salvage values will tend to underestimate the investment response to a lowering of taxes on marketing board crops. 69 l l l " , ? K. “3 K3 “1 E Xl/Xl Figure 3.4 Aggregation Problems Under normal circumstances when we try to aggre- gate these individual farm-firm effects of government and marketing board pricing policies based on the true demand curves for resources, there would be another bias from the downward sloping nature of the aggregate demand curve facing all farmers. We shall not go into the nature of this bias because of our assumption that all farmers in any production period face an aggregate demand curve that is infinitely elastic at the prices set by the marketing boards. If we summed individual farm effects based on individual MVP curves, we get another bias. The nature of this bias will not be examined here. r3 m‘ if m L An :1; 15 that fame} equilibriun e." 3‘. ,.‘ 1 lsuCl’ aao la: 5 .s; Lfa$lLiOhal NJ \‘. ‘ H‘- v o... SL8“; 'W. E'Iiéence of , 49.: _ I MSnell in? T: ., “ *6 had cia was I y‘ (T) 3 t: (D O Q c; ,J 'F"‘(V“v\§. nu \ duke; at), G: ‘ p e- ‘Qrfi-i n “‘L.‘g -\ G 5; ~ “g SUr UI R )- s .- PH .sJ H 9uCc' . 50 I a 9'» "is 3:. on '71.. 1‘s: 70 The Implicit Assumption of Allocative Equilibrium: SchulEz‘s Hypothesis as Our Point of Departure An implicit assumption of the foregoing analysis is that farmers in the Northern States achieve allocative equilibrium with respect to such traditional resources as labor and land which still constitute the bulk of value added in agriculture in Nigeria. Time was when the need was to empirically test Professor T. W. Schultz's hypothe~ 22 with respect to the use of sis of allocative equilibrium traditional factors. Most of the evidence that is in is consistent with his hypothesis. Norman's data show evidence of allocative equilibrium in the use of tra- ditional inputs like land and labor in Southern Zaria.23 If we had data to estimate the input demand elasticities then we could use these to predict changes in resource use for given changes in taxes on crop and subsidies on inputs brought about by government and marketing boards. Government and Marketing Board Taxation of Crops and Subsidies on Ipputs: A Second-BestfiiProblem If labor produces the bulk of value added in farming activities in the Northern States and it is not being subsidized, in the presence of taxes on a crop produced by labor, if you want to minimize distortions in the amounts of labor employed, what is the compensating amount of subsidy on the other factor(s) to keep the quantity of labor employed constant? The theory of sccné-‘oest sa scre of your r cannot say '3: ‘— .'.,,'.', . , 6 u. cuer a“ dY . swag; 5" my: v- ..tnal ..u..a I For c. :A 'o . .:r:1.;zer re ' “‘Ffi‘. I! s — nouksoou' 'fl’a: Li;“.3r ‘ U -S\ w I ug‘a "“ :.‘,’.C-' A - ‘ amt i ..o o . '_[_l “ \Va., “He r: L. I ‘U (‘l- U‘Ill t! n _ t.“ L h. “He acorn-“ h ‘Q.1\a‘.. I 71 second-best says that given that you have a violation of some of your marginality conditions for an optimum, we cannot say apriori whether we would move towards or further away from the optimum by violating more marginality conditions. For example, with X1 and X2 denoting labor and fertilizer respectively in a Cobb-Douglas production function, what are the required changes in the net acquisition prices of fertilizers paid by farmers and in the net crop price received by farmers to keep the profit maximizing (equilibrium) quantity of labor employed on farms constant? In many important policy making circles in Nigeria, policy makers are wondering whether, given existing taxes on crops imposed by State Governments and their marketing boards, it might very well not be better to just compensate farmers by increasing the subsidies on inputs like fertilizers, chemicals, sprays, etc. For the Cobb-Douglas form, let X1, X2, X3, X4 denote labor of a given skill, fertilizer, chemicals, and land respectively, i.e., 4 Y = AX x x x , Z Bi'< 1; Bi > o, (i = 1,....,4). (8) From the necessary conditions for equilibrium with respect to only the off-farm acquisition price and the MVP, the true demand functions for labor, fertilizer, chemicals, art land hold 1 L 112,113, and Xil i,[=l ”331 (36) abs 1109): =‘ l l-E 72 and land holding only the net acquisition prices of XI, X2, X3, and X4 and the net crop price constant are, in log: 1 10 X. = 10 A + 10 P + X 10 + X -l 9 1 4 l 9 g (uy y) .Br gBr ( . Br ) r#i .r#i 1 - 2 B. . 1 i=1 109(Aipx.a) - ( X. Br-l)logBi - X BrlongPx a)]; 1 r#i r#1 r i, r = 1, ..., 4. (8a) From (8a) above, — 1 — d log x1 — 1—81-82-83-84 [(82+B3+B4 1) d log (Alexia) + d log (uyPy) ‘ 82 d log (XZsza) - 83 d log (XBPXBa) - 84 d log (A (8b) 4Px4a)] where we have set dK = 0, where _ l K - 1-8 [82 log 82 + 83 log 83 + 84 log 84 1'32'83'84 -(82+B3+B4-1) log 81], all constants, involving the given output elasticities of the four inputs. Now, set d log X1 = O and solve for d log (Aszza) d 1 ' P 09 (By y) I d log (Allea) l P 09 (uy y) d Setting dlog X r; “us-fee “ l 2 3 4 ““31 says t‘r ‘ um, ""1 would he 73 Setting dlog X = O, 1 i:§1-B:-B3-B4 [82 d log (Aszza) + 83 d log (A3px3a) + 84 d log (A4Px4a) - (82+B3+B4-1) d log (11pxa)] = 1-81-82283-84 d log (uyPy) ; (8C) then for given net acquisition prices of chemicals and land, d log X1 = 0 implies that24 d log (AZPx a) 2 l =—>O dlog (uyPy) 82 which says that as the net crop price received by farmers goes up by 1 per cent, the net acquisition price that they would have to pay for fertilizers to keep the quantity of labor constant goes up by the inverse of the output elasticity of fertilizers. Fertilizers still contribute a minor share of value added in Nigerian agriculture. It would intuitively appear that the smaller the factor share of fertilizers in Northern States agriculture, then the larger would be the required compensating fall in the net acquisition price of fertilizers for a given increase in taxes on a crop if the quantity of labor is to remain unchanged. For the above case we see that the smaller the output elasticity of fertilizers, the larger the "required" percentage re: lizers to com producer pric labor. For e elasticity of producer pric sating" fall of 20 per cer We d? either at thl do have the from Noman' -~ I “rlsation : 2dashes al; I: PIOductié “mess h A ‘ Mrvps' Kar‘ d L' urn“ 74 percentage reduction in net acquisition price of ferti- lizers to compensate for a l per cent fall in the net producer price of a crop produced by both fertilizer and labor. For example, if fertilizers have an output elasticity of 0.05, then a l per cent fall in the net producer price of,say,groundnuts would require a "compen- sating" fall in the net acquisition price of fertilizers of 20 per cent. We do not have the output elasticity of fertilizers either at the farm level or at the States level. But we do have the output elasticity of land in Southern Zaria from Norman's study.25 The government does undertake irrigation projects, reclaims lands, takes conservation measures all of which can be seen as subsidizing land used in production. If we want to minimize distortion in the amounts of labor employed as a result of taxation of crops, what is the compensating amount of subsidy on land through the above projects for given taxes on crops? Using Norman's output elasticity for land, we find for cotton/COWpeas/sweet potatoes crop mixture on ggga land that a 1 per cent fall in the net producer price of cotton would "require" a "compensating" fall in the net acquisition price of land of 1.857 per cent; on cotton (ggga land), it would require a compensating fall in net acquisition prices of land of 2.422 per cent; in groundnut production (gona land), a l per cent fall in the net producer priC sling" fall cert. These tie governme groundnuts a requires irr estimates ar each carketi the levels < cannot appn can write AIIV as 7S producer price of groundnuts would "require" a "compen- sating" fall in net acquisition prices of land of 2.746 per cent. These required compensating investments in land by the government in the presence of taxation of cotton and groundnuts are particularly relevant for ggga land which requires irrigation for all season cultivation (quoted 26 If at the beginning of estimates are for gona land). each marketing period, the marketing board in determining the levels of taxes and subsidies determines that it cannot appreciably influence world market prices, than we can write d 1°9 (AZsza) d log A _ 2 _ 1 d iog (uyPy) d log u Y _ 82 so that instead of dealing in net crOp prices and net input acquisition prices after all taxes and subsidies have been netted out, we can talk directly of percentage changes in proportions of unit crop price received and unit input price paid. Starting from equilibrium employment of labor, then for given changes in taxes on a crop and subsidies on land, d log A d log u 2 Y Allv 0 according as AHV ax F; , 2 where Axl represents a "change" in X Consi the largest f States, then to minimize c the "compense maximizing (z Pain, the " the compensa sition price reduction it In t iemand curs. me Product 76 Considering a variant of the above, if labor gets the largest factor share in agriculture in the Northern States, then given taxes on, say, groundnuts, if "we" want to minimize distortion in the employment of labor, what is the "compensating subsidy" on labor to keep the profit maximizing (equilibrium) quantity of labor unchanged? Again, the "special elasticity" we are interested in is the compensating percentage reduction in the net acqui— sition price paid on labor for a given one percentage reduction in the net producer price of, say, groundnuts. In the case of using a single MVP curve as the demand curve, from (8a), and assuming only X1 and x4 in the production function, logX=—l—-log(}\P )+ 1 log(uP)+B4 logX+K 1 81-1 1 xla l-Bl y y 1-81 4 _ l l where K — -——— log 8 + ———— log A 1-81 1 1-81 from which after setting d log X1 = O and assuming d log X4 = 0, d log (A P ) _ l xla 81 l d log (uyPy) = 81—1 = 1' which says that a l per cent fall in the net producer price of groundnuts or cotton requires a "compensating" l per cent fall in the net acquisition price of all labor employed if the quantity of labor employed is to remain constar in the case 0 tie price of production f u which Say 5 t‘ “a. ~.-..ton produ fall in the 77 remain constant. The corresponding "special elasticity"27 in the case of the true demand curve for labor, assuming the price of land fixed is, with only X1 and X4 in the production function d log (AlPX a) l l 2 )0 d P l- 109 (uy y) 54 which says that as the board reduces the net groundnut or cotton producer price by l per cent, the compensating fall in the net acquisition price of labor would be the inverse of one minus the output elasticity of land. Table 3.4 shows some empirical results. A parallel policy question is the amount of compen- sating subsidy on fertilizers used on Northern State farms for a given decrease in the net price of a marketing board crop if the amount of land employed in these crops is to remain the same. Policy makers are currently concerned about the diversion of land from groundnut production in the Northern States to other crops in the face of the relatively heavy taxes on groundnuts in recent years. There is an increasing competition between groundnuts and the other food crops in Kano State (the main producing state) with respect to the allocation of land. A major problem in cotton production in North Central State, North West State, and North East State is the competition between cotton and food crops for land. 33L}: Mr" 2. Groundn: m la: 78 TABLE 3.4.--Compensating (Percentage) Subsidies on Labor for a One Per Cent Decrease in Net Price of a Marketing Board Crop so as to Keep the Quantity of Labor Employed on Northern State Farms Constant. Compensating Percentage - a Enterprise Sub51dy on Labor Per Cent 1. Cotton Production on gona land; 84 = 0.4128b 1.702 2. Groundnuts Production on gona land; 84 = .3641 1.57 3. Guinea corn/Groundnuts Production on gona land; 84 = .6695 3.025 4. Millet/Guinea Corn/Groundnuts Production on gona land; 84 = .6429 2.800 5. Cotton/Cowpeas/Sweet Potatoes 1 B4 = .5385 2.166 Source: For output elasticities of land, D. W. Norman, An Economic Study of Three Villages in Zaria Province: Part II Input-Output Relationships (Zaria: Institute for Agricultural Research, Ahmadu Bello Uni— versity, 1970), p. 126. aCompensating percentage subsidy on labor is defined as d log (11px a) 1 _ 1 b84 is the output elasticity of land. "'- "'O i Gwen 1 ‘ JEC‘IEEE 4 IQ;?II ‘ 'obu y. ' ‘r‘vgv was ..e 79 Given that there are taxes on cotton and groundnuts, what degrees of subsidies are required on these resources to keep their quantities employed in the production of marketing board crops constant? The question is important because of the allocative distortions introduced by taxation-~these compensating subsidies are a way of coping with the adverse effects of these taxes with respect to resource use in Northern States farming. The application of chemicals in groundnuts and cotton has great potential for high payoffs.28 If the government wants to subsidize these chemicals (for seed dressing and spraying) to compensate for taxes on cotton and groundnuts so that the (equilibrium) quantity of land employed does not change, then, from (8a) the required percentage fall in the net acquisition price of chemicals for a l per cent fall in the net price of the marketing board crop is: d log (ABPx a) 3 =1>o d log (uyPy) F; ' i.e., the inverse of the output elasticity of chemicals. Similarly if the government wants to subsidize these chemicals to compensate for taxes on cotton and groundnuts so that the (equilibrium) quantity of chemicals used in these crops does not change, then, from (8) and after setting d log X3 = O, the required percentage fall ‘n the m . cent in dlc 3; "J n ,, 1 "”RI .‘I.1'.O S Rf‘bh HV‘uv'Jn ' \ '9 ‘1‘» on 3;“: I‘n ...e (e Q: ’I D H v“. .. , fi.! 1.“ ts f!) zastic. . V .. “Main: "3' be 80 in the net acquisition price of chemicals for a l per cent fall in the net price of the marketing board crop is: d log (ABPx a) 3 :: 1 >0 d log (uyPy) 1-81-82-84 which says that as the board reduces the net groundnut or cotton producer price by l per cent, the compensating fall in the net acquisition price of chemicals required to keep the (equilibrium) quantity of chemicals employed in these crops unchanged is the inverse of one minus the sum of the output elasticities of the other inputs in the production function. In the case of fertilizers, the corresponding required percentage fall in the net acquisition price of fertilizers for a l per cent fall in the net price of the marketing board crop is: d log (AZPx ) 12:. = 1 > O . With the perfect competition assumption, the output elasticities of inputs become their factor shares and arguments about required compensating subsidies on inputs can be restated in terms of factor income shares. From the last two results, it is evident that the less important a given resource is in production (as measured by its output elasticity) the more it has to be subsidized for a given percentage fall in the net producer V '1! :rice of t IESC‘QICE l stirs the 13 D CREE "is“ ] :‘bivwo V 3:56 fid'.’ large ta have ti 3.“. hand Orcari - 4 ”4-1 81 price of the marketing board crop if the quantity of this resource employed is to remain constant. Let us extend our results to include the case in which the initial quantity on hand is fixed where its MVP is between its off-farm acquisition cost and its salvage price. From our earlier analysis, small taxes in this case have no effect on total resource employment while large taxes lead to salvaging and disinvestment of the input. This implies that for small taxes, no compensating subsidies are required to keep quantities of inputs on hand at their initial levels. Large taxes lead to disinvestment in resources. What is required in this case is compensating policy action to prevent this disinvestment. 2’ In Figure 3.5, EE, EE’, EE , lea' and les all have their previous meanings. With initial quantity of X1 on hand at K1 (as arises, for example, from errors of organization) and taxes on the marketing board crop leading to the adjusted MVP curve EE’, there is no need for compensating subsidy on X1 for its quantity to remain constant at K1 because there is no incentive for its quantity to change even in the absence of subsidies. With larger taxes leading to EE”, there is an incentive to salvage Xl by the amount K2K1‘ To prevent this, policy makers may "tax" the salvage value of X1: if it is off- farm salvage value, they may lower this to P; S; if it is 1 on-farm salvage value, they may "tax" this to bring it 82 $ll Ek‘ E’m\\\ \ \ 6,6 EllK ’ \ PXLS L_.___ _. _ _ .’ I I l I K; K) Er ”In? Figure 3.5 down to P; 3' However, we do not know why policy makers 1 would be interested in maintaining resources at production levels where market acquisition costs are not being covered! Government and Marketing Board Taxation o Crops Expressed as Taxes on Resources Used in Farming One possible alternative method of investigating the effect of government and marketing board taxation of crops and subsidy on inputs is to express all taxes as equivalent taxes on factors of production--labor (family and hired), land fertilizer, hoes, matchets as implied by 83 29 The owners of productive Johnson many years ago. resources can regard them as items of wealth, the returns on which are the present value of net income streams earned by these resources. The present value of the gross income streams to a productive resource can be approximated by the present value of the (gross) expected marginal value I. product of the resource where the expected prices used are the potential producer (crop) price in the absence of all ’M‘--‘n—.__ 4 .- taxation of crops. From this must be netted out the present value of the per production period costs of using this productive resource (the user costs which refer to the costs incurred from the physical depreciation of the assets which is a function of the intensity of use of these resources, obsolescence costs, etc.). Then the capital value of a productive resource over the relevant horizon (which may be the economic length of life of the asset or the length of time the farmer plans to remain in business) can be represented as the discounted sum of the gross marginal value product minus the present value of per period costs of using the productive asset, i.e., u MVP; - T* + S O t HMS K = u MVP - T + o o o t 1 II=Irfrt * n n 1+ . n ( r3) = 3'1 j where K0 is the capital value of the productive resource now, TE is the cost of using the resource in period t, I s“ 84 “t is the proportion of expected MVP of the resource received by the farmer in period t (MVP*), rj is the per period opportunity cost of funds tied up in this durable asset, s; is the expected salvage value of the resource in time n and the price used in calculating the MVP is the potential producer price in the absence of all taxation. The impact of taxation of crops that is not offset by subsidies is to lower the capital value of resources. Farmers engaged in the production of marketing board crops suffer a loss in capital value of their initial resources. This causes a redistribution of income: farmers of marketing board crops lose on the capital value of their resources; others who benefit from the use of this taxation in social investments (health, education, roads, etc.) gain. We have a non-Pareto better adjustment. The Data If we had adequate time series data on the use of any resource (fertilizers, chemicals, insecticides, land, labor, chemicals, etc.) we could estimate the elasticity parameters. Such time series data just do not exist for any reasonable stretch of time. Where some data exist for short periods as in the case of fertilizers it is not clear whether the figures reflect demand for these resources or they reflect the efficiency levels of the Extensions Department of the Ministry of Agriculture and Natural Resources.30 The "frustrated demand" resulting *“wMI-r 'M.-__ . .l b, I) 85 ;he inefficiency of government officials does not Ip in these figures. Even where the data on resource rption are available, they are not likely to be 1 down according to crop use. Table 3.5 shows .izer consumption in the Northern States, 1950-1967. From the above model one would expect the demand :rtilizers on Northern States farms to be a function : acquisition price of fertilizers and the net :er (crop) prices received after all subsidies and of the government and the marketing board have been I out. From theory we expect demand for fertilizers a function of the real price of fertilizers. Even had data on the subsidized prices of fertilizers, a :te theory does not expect real fertilizer price to .n most of the demand for fertilizers. The amount of information about the mean of the Iility distribution of the incremental yield from the :ation of fertilizers plays a crucial role in the ,on of fertilizers. One can expect that in those of the Northern States with demonstration plots, , and other exposure to fertilizer use, the proba- ' distribution of the incremental yield of fertilizers :s "tighter." Differential access to different types 31 will account for differences in fertilizer ‘ormation . across the Northern States. In other words, a ‘te analysis would incorporate elements of the A..- 86 :.oaQMaam>m uoc: mamme .m.c "ouoz nMMWIdmm .ucmusmq .M .0 "mooaum umuaaauuom oouao Iamndm co mocwoa>m owumuumom uom .o .m .aabma .wusuasoanom o0 ucoEuummoo amuoomm ”mommav muscocaouo co mdouorwosum on» NO uuomom .nouvoma «vumlaa wands .nmmwldmm .uocaoaaom .mouomma "mooaum unconsoum Mom .omumb .mm .Aanma .Eoumwm onmom mCauoxumz map so oocmnoocou amcoaumcuoucav couuou ocm muscocsouo molmcauoxumz on» you mucosmmcmuua oaumosoo on» Ca mannoum on» «o mo>unm 4 .aamEmH .a .d can whoaauaa .o .2 some 5.32 517: 032. ..uwlollmm .Hafimfiam $9.83 683m .888 not .2 828 £33m cumnuuoz xam on» Ca Emumoum c0audnauumao Houaaauumm ocuImcaomm mannoum .ucousma .x .O nonooma nooma .moonummw amoaumaumpm waummaz cnozuuoz Eoum monomma mousmao c0aumsdmcou umuaaauuom "oousom oa maa hma mmm.o mom.o oom.hv homa Na mma aoa omm.v mmb.v onm.mm ooma .m.c oma aoa ama.N th.N oam.ma moma .m.c mma oma mmm.a oon.a oam.aa coma .m.c ama mva ama.a moN.a oom.m moma .m.c ama mva mom mmm moN.N Noma va mma mma omm mhm omm.a aoma .m.c oma ova mma Nma omm ooma .m.c mma Nba mma mva mao.a mmma .m.c oma ooa moa oma mmm.a mmma .m.c oma ova mm I moa Nob hmma .m.c mma mma mha mwa 0am.a omma .m.c oma boa vm aoa mob mmma .m.c oma boa mm mm vao Gmoa .m.c mva moa mm ooa woo mmma .m.: oma ova mma hma mbm.a mmma .m.c oma ova 50m 0mm oom.m amma .m.c 00a 00a ooa boa om” omma c09\zm ooauomma ooanomma ooauomma ooaummma mace mHQNHHflUHMW MUfiHm woflhnw HGUDUOHQ COHflQEaamCOU HMUOB Ham» 87 decision-making processes of farm managers and factors like the type of communal rights over land, the human elements of their interaction with extensions men, the amount of peak season labor available for application of fertilizer and weeding of incremental weed—growth and any analysis of the effects of government and marketing taxation and subsidies has to reckon with these factors. Table 3.6 shows the consumption of fertilizers in Kano State 1960/61- 1969/70. TABLE 3.6.--Fertilizer Consumption in Kano State, Nigeria, 1960/61-1969/70 (Tons). Year Superphosphate Sulphate of Ammonia Total 1960/61 200 n.a. 200 1961/62 430 14 444 1962/63 750 196 856 1963/64 1,200 55 1,255 1964/65 1,200 200 1,400 1965/66 2,240 362 2,602 1966/67 3,500 350 3,850 1967/68 n.a. n.a. n.a. 1968/69 8,500 3,015 11,515 1969/70 1,815 508 2,323 Source: Kano State Survey of Agriculture, 1971. Note: n.a. means "not available." We do not have any reliable data on the main resources used in farming in the Northern States either on a time-series basis or on a cross-sectional basis covering all the states. 88 Summary and Conclusions The first part of the chapter provided a model for analyzing the allocative distortions induced by government and marketing board taxation, with respect to the relative quantities of crops produced and resources used. With differential taxation of cotton and groundnuts detrimental to groundnuts, the relative quantity of cotton was higher than would have been the case in the absence of all taxation wherever cotton and groundnuts were substitutes in production. Implicit in the model is the fact that food crops, relative to cotton and groundnuts, were produced in quantities larger than would have been the case in the absence of all taxation since food crops bore zero rates of taxation and cotton and groundnuts had positive rates of taxation most of the period examined, wherever food crops and these marketing boards crops were substitutes in production. This is all the more surprising 33 The given the current trend of rising food prices. fundamental indictment of government and marketing board taxation on this score is that it has affected the patterns of specialization in the country: farmers of marketing board crOps have been induced to produce more food than would have been optimal in the absence of all taxation while other areas with a comparative advantage in food crop production alone have been neglected in government policies, e.g., the Middle Belt. 89 The basic model was then extended to take account of the possibility that it may not pay the farm-firm to vary the initial quantity of the resource on hand, i.e., there is neither investment nor disinvestment in this resource. The major analytical result was that investment- disinvestment responses to changes in taxes and subsidies were, in some cases, different from those predicted by the neoclassical model. This was specially the case with resources that were initially (economically) fixed in the absence of taxes and subsidies. The model was able to predict, in response to taxes on marketing board crops, not only acquisitions of resources below what they would have been in the absence of taxes but also to predict the salvaging of some of the initial quantity on hand until, in equilibrium, salvage value equals the MVP of the resource. The empirical evidence shows that land (acreage) in cotton and groundnut farms in the Northern States are, through the induced response to real input price changes, smaller than would have been the case in the absence of taxes on these crops. 'This expected reduced acreage arises on two counts. First, taxes on cotton and ground- nuts reduce land clearings or acquisitions below what they would have been in the absence of taxes. This is signifi- cant at a time when policy makers in the North-Eastern State, North-West State, and North Central State are 90 concerned about the fact that farmers are not planting suitable available land to these crops. Many production expansion programs over the next decade for most of the Northern States rely on expanded new acreage as well as improvement of existing acres. The finding that these taxes can be expected to adversely affect expanded acreage in these crops has implications for these production expansion programs. Second, these taxes lead to salvaging and disinvestment of the initial quantities on hand. The initial acreage is allocated to competing crops on the basis of opportunity-cost on the farm. It is not surprising that many farmers in the Northern States are known to have diverted acreages away from groundnuts to food production. Where cotton and groundnuts compete for land, this allo— cation must have been influenced largely by the differ- ential taxation of cotton and groundnuts. These taxes have had the same effect on labor. First, taxes on cotton and groundnuts have induced farmers to acquire less labor than they would have acquired in the absence of taxes. This reduces the rate of entry of new farmers into the production of these crops and it decreases the purchases of hired labor below what they would have been in the absence of these taxes. Peak season labor is a major constraint in the production of these crOps. Taxes reduce purchases of hired labor during these peak seasons below what they would have been in the absence of taxes 91 on these crops. Second, taxes have increased the rate of exit of labor from the farm sector: as taxes become large, not only are labor purchases below what they would have been without taxes but some of the labor on hand in the farm-firm as well as in the farm sector as a whole is salvaged. Labor will continue to be salvaged until, in equilibrium, the salvage value of the labor of a given age and skill equals its marginal value product in cotton or groundnuts. For the older farmers, their relevant salvage values might be the present values of their expected marginal value product in food production. Alternatively, their salvage values might be the present values of their expected marginal value products in off-farm rural activi- ties. For the younger farmers and school leavers, the relevant salvage value may be the present value of the expected marginal value product in the urban areas. When wages in urban areas rise from minimum wage legislation in the presence of taxes on marketing board crops, there is accelerated salvaging of young farmers and school leavers from the rural areas until in equilibrium, their salvage values equal their MVP's in cotton and groundnuts. Our framework is potentially powerful for modeling the (tremendous) off-farm migration experienced in recent years. Unlike most existing models, this model's explicit focus is on the economic activities of people in rural areas as these are affected by national policies. Too \V I. J. S‘. We. we I n I. 92 often, the focus has been on the urban centers. A frame- work that is capable of explaining the impact of national policies on labor absorption in rural areas is potentially useful. For those resources that were economically fixed initially, the model predicts that there would be salvaging of some of the initial quantity on hand as taxes increase. Not only are the stocks of these resources employed on these farms less than they would have been, but they are also being worked less intensively than would have been the case in the absence of all taxation. Some resources may be fixed when off-farm acqui— sition and salvage values are considered. But from our apriori knowledge of the ease with which resources are shifted between crops in the cotton-groundnuts-foods economy of the Northern States, we infer that farmers must be allocating these fixed resources on an on-farm oppor- tunity cost basis. These allocative responses are known to be sensitive to changes in taxes on marketing board crops. This further strengthens our empirical results on the allocative effects of these taxes on relative outputs of cotton, groundnuts, and foods and on resource use. Given the fact that these resources still produce the bulk of value added in Northern States farming, these taxation policies by implication have inhibited the generation of private saving, investment and the formation and use of farm-produced capital. --.J ll (3 a ‘1' ll 93 The third section of the chapter is more of the nature of a planning tool: even though fertilizers, chemicals and new inputs are insignificant in Northern States farming today, if policy makers are conscious of the instituitonal reality of marketing boards but are concerned about the allocative distortions of these taxes with respect to resource use, then what are the compen- sating subsidies on these resources so that their quantities and.their intensity of use remain unchanged? These conmensating subsidies are shown, within the Cobb-Douglas production function framework, to be related to the output elasticities of these resources. Calculations are then made using available estimated output elasticities of land and labor. This "second-best" approach has potential ftxr planning purposes--budget allocations to input Stuosidies can rationally be related to expected tax rates or: marketing board crops. "n—oa— —_ v . nun R.- b-LJ Rib Clo am DIP... 1.0- -uu‘ c «Q ‘. HUM a: .‘h‘ IHU R44 AV Vin FOOTNOTES 1Insofar as marketing costs of government and quasi—government agencies are unlikely to be lower than competitive marketing costs that would have obtained in the absence of these government agencies, then the marketing board surplus is the lower bound of the marketing board component of the taxes on farmers. This point has been almost entirely neglected in discussions of marketing board policies. 2One way of looking at this is to express specific taxes as their ad valorem tax equivalents yielding the same revenue. Their effects on outputs and prices are the same under competition (see R. Musgrave, The Theor of Public Finance (New York: McGraw Hill, 1959; C. Bishop, "The Effects of Specific and Ad Valorem Taxes," Quarterly Journal of Economics (1968). 3This formulation does not preclude positive initial quantities of resources on hand, resources which can then be presumed to have salvage values different from acquisition values. It admits of positive initial quanti- ties on hand up to the point where the acquisition price of the resource equals its MVP. For cases in which the MVP of the resource is between acquisition price and salvage value and when it is below salvage value for the initial quantities on hand, see p. 48. 4Some common combinations in Zaria Province have been documented by Norman: millet/guineacorn; guineacorn/ groundnuts, guineacorn/cowpeas; groundnuts/cowpeas: okra/pepper; cotton/cowpeas; cotton/cowpeas. See D. W. Norman, op. cit. 5Behrman did the pioneering work in this area for Thailand. See J. Behrman, Supplpresppnse in Under- develo ed A riculture (Amsterdam: North-HOliand Publishing Company, 19685. 94 I,“ _-7 ‘3. O NJ- 7. -b H" 'u . I .o of! EH! .5 .rIl 95 6Alternatively, farmers may employ "certainty equivalence" prices. 7We want to emphasize the assumption of initial equilibrium, i.e., that for constant relative prices, it does not pay to reorganize the farm. This point was not given adequate emphasis in Clark Edwards' original good treatment. See Clark Edwards, "Resource Fixity and Farm Organization," Journal of Farm Economics (November, 1959). 8This may arise from errors of organization, imperfect knowledge and foresight, etc. 91h this case, a resource that was initially fixed at K1 becomes variable as a result of subsidies. 10 . . In this sense, the neocla531cal theory over- estimates the induced reduction in resource use in response to taxes on crops. 11In the case of allocating a given quantity of the resource among competing crops, this acquisition price equals, in equilibrium, the MVP of the resource in all uses (i.e., the on-farm opportunity.cost of the resource). The two crops (e.g., cotton and groundnuts), one fixed input (e.g., land) case is only a special case of the model given on p. 36. The acquisition cost of an acre of land to be used in cotton is the foregone marginal value product of land in groundnuts and conversely for the acquisition of land from cotton production for use in groundnut production. 12Both land and labor are nonhomogeneous. References to resources are to resources of a given quality. 13Norman has both a lower and an upper bound for the annual cost of services of an acre of land in Southern Zaria. In gona land (upland field), this lower bound is 17 shillings and the upper bound is 100 shillings. On gaudana land (lowland field) the lower bound is 47 shillings and the upper bound is 370 shillings. In all likelihood (in the absence of government irrigation and reclamation projects, etc.), the farmer bears the full cost of this land. See D. W. Norman, An Economic Study of Three Villages in Zaria Province, Part II, Input-Oupput Relationships, p. 125. Bearing the full real costs of land is the common practice in the Northern States. He found the cost of non- family labor to be 0.51 shillings/man hour which he also uses to approximate the opportunity cost of family labor. This is a simplication but it is convenient. A: est N Mir: 4" 96 14P. Samuelson, Foundations of Economic Analysis (New York: Atheneum, 1965). 15Glenn L. Johnson, "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis," Journal of Farm Economics (1960). 16Heady, in an analysis of the effect of leasing arrangements on farm size, derives demand curves for inputs that are based on MVP curves. This introduces bias in the estimation of effects. Such an analysis should be able to predict the effects of changes in leasing arrangements on farm size--but such estimates would be biased if we use MVP curves as input demand curves. Ulveling, in a comment on the Heady article, fails to bring out the basic problem--the question of what is being held constant in the derivation of input demand curves. He does not, for example, make clear whether his equations at the bottom of p. 142 are to be solved simultaneously to get the true demand function or whether each marginality condition (equilibrium) is to be solved to get the (special) input demand function. Much of our own analysis of the nature of the bias should be seen as a critique of Heady and Ulveling. See E. Heady, "Optimal Farm Size," American Journal of Agricultural Economics (February, 1971); E. Ulveling, Comment, American Journal of Agricultural Economics (February, 19723. 17For other sources of bias, see p. 68. 18This implicitly assumes input use is a function of its acquisition price and crop price. 19What is "true" in some sense depends on your assumptions. We use "true" here in the sense that it is more general-~the demand curve that allows other input quantities to vary is more general than one which does not. "More general" could be used in place of "true"; use of the latter here is the author's preference. 20There is consequently a tendency to under- estimate the reduction in resource use that results from an increase in taxes on marketing board crops using the MVP curve as the demand curve for the resource. 21 n’(P)-n (IJP)=—L----1-—= -82 x ' “y y x ' y y 1-81 1-81-82 (1—81) (1-81—82) 1 l N 'A—n- - -_...._ 97 22See T. W. Schultz, T£ansforming Traditional Agriculture (Yale University Press, i964?) Schultz's hypothesis is general enough to include the case in which, with fixed resources to be allocated among competing crops, the relevant acquisition price is the on-farm opportunity cost. 23Letting X1 and X2 denote labor and land respectively in a Cobb-Douglas framework, Norman finds these results: Millet/guinea corn (gona land): 8 =M3§5925, 82 = 0.3189, 81+82 = 0.9104, MVP = 0.58, P = 0.51 => = 1.14; MVP = 66.11, x x a x l l x a 2 2 = .66 Fadama land (all crops): 81 = 0.2746, 0.90; MVP = 641.85, P x x a 2 2 x a ll L») \I 0 ll sweet potatoes (gona land): 81 = 1.05553 32 = 0°5385’ 81+82 = MVPx 1 = 1.22 1.5941; MVP = 0.62; P 0.51; x x P a l l xla Source: For output elasticities, see D. W. Norman, op. cit. 24The same result holds if it is the quantity of land that policy makers want to keep constant. 25D. W. Norman, op. cit. 26Note: These "compensating" subsidies on land in the face of taxes on cotton and groundnuts are the inverse of the output elasticity of land in each crop obtained from Norman's study. ICIA Phi c- Flu. VII. I f\ 98 27This "special elasticity," like the ones before it, is not derived from any obvious behavioral postulate. However, we could conceive of government officials who are concerned about distortions introduced by government and marketing board taxation in the amounts of labor employed (including induced off-farm migration) but who are equally conscious of the institutional reality of the marketing boards reasoning along these lines: "at the going average rates of taxation imposed by the government and marketing boards, what would be the required compensating subsidies on the price of labor that farmers pay or the price of fertilizers, chemicals, etc., that they pay so as to keep people on the farms and, say, stem the off-farm migration?" Such implicit reasoning does indeed exist among Nigerian policy makers today. 28Johnson states, " . . . Nigeria is unlike many countries of the world in that it is not private land owners who exploit the Nigerian farmer; instead, if the Nigerian farmer is exploited by those who control income from land, it must be the government which would be doing so via marketing board levies on the economic rent of land." See Glenn L. Johnson, "Factor Markets and the Problem of Economic Development," in W. W. McPherson, ed., Economic Development of Tropical Agriculture (University of Florida Press, 1968?. It Should be pointed out that Johnson's point is valid for all resources engaged in the production of marketing board crops receiving no net subsidies. 29"Fertilizers and insecticides are now purchased in bulk by State Ministries of Natural Resources and distributed to farmers through the extension services and local agents, but in some cases adequate supplies are not available when the farmers need them." Re ort of the Stud Grou on Cotton and Other Fibres (Lagos: e eral Department 0 Agricu ture, , p. 8. " . . . Nigeria’s agricultural output is being severely limited by the non-availability of inputs. No where is the effect of this greater or more forcefully indicated than in the groundnut area . . . demand . . . is so strong that it finally changes hands at full cost, or higher, even though it is intended to sell for half the actual cost." Repprt of the Study Group on Groundnuts Lagos: Federal Department of Agriculture, 1971), p. 38. 99 30Glenn L. Johnson, Managerial Processes of Mid- n Farmers (Iowa State University Press, 19615. 31Some of this is due to the poor transport tructure coupled with poor storage facilities. f1 vr‘ CHAPTER IV SALES OF CROPS TO THE MARKETING BOARD AND GOVERNMENT AND MARKETING BOARD REVENUE FROM TAXES ON CROPS Introduction The second objective of this study is to examine the quantitative impact on tax revenue from cotton and groundnuts of paying farmers (generally) higher prices. This will enable us to see to what extent, if any, the resulting (crop tax) revenue loss can be offset by the positive effect (if any) of higher prices on sales of these crops on the marketing board. The chapter is divided into two main sections. The first section examines the determinants of revenue from taxation of crops, or the relationship between taxes on marketing board crops and the resulting revenue; the second part argues that fundamental to the revenue potential of any crop is the underlying investment-disinvestment process. It will be assumed in this chapter that compe— titive conditions exist in the cotton and groundnut 100 1W. 1‘- 101 sectors, that farmers in the aggregate, in any marketing period selling a crop to the board, face an infinitely elastic demand curve at the producer price fixed by the board. The Determinapts of Government Revenue From Taxation of Crops The immediate determinants of government and marketing board revenue from taxation of a given crop are the quantities offered for sale to the board and the tax rates imposed per unit of the crop or on an ad valorem basis. The quantity of any crop offered for sale to the board depends in some way on the total output of the crop produced, the amount of the crop consumed by the farmers themselves, the amount sold to the non-farm consuming public or more generally the amount sold on the Nigerian domestic market through private market channels and the amounts sold to neighboring countries (e.g., Niger, Cameroon, Dahomey) through smugglers. The quantity of a marketing board crop that is produced would depend on the net producer price of this crop relative to the prices of closely competitive crops; the relative availability of new and superior inputs in the various crops and the amounts of 2933 normative and non-normative information concerning the expected values and variances of the probability distributions of yields, ‘V‘ 4- :0 ah ‘ v- on my 4. 'F ,‘1 " In I.. '6 o I,‘ 102 prices, costs, technological parameters, human behavior, etc. In the presence of risk aversion, one would expect the elasticity of output of a given marketing board crop with respect to the relative standard deviation of its price to be negative. The consumption of a marketing board crop by its producers (total or per capita basis) themselves would depend on the relative price of the crop and the real income of the producers. The amount of groundnuts sold on the Nigerian domestic market depend on net producer prices for ground- nuts and/or groundnut products like locally made groundnut oil relative to the net producer prices being paid by the board and the ease with which the crop can be transported to local markets in the country from surplus areas. The domestic market has exercised a strong pull on marketing board crops in recent years,1 an influence particularly strengthened by some shortages created during the recent civil disturbances. It has paid producers and middlemen engaged in groundnuts and palm oil production and marketing to divert large quantities of these crops away from the marketing boards into the Nigerian domestic (internal) market. If, for example, the consumption demand for groundnuts is a function of income and population (for simplicity, assume own-price constant), then the percentage increase in its consumption over a year would depend on u. l 103 the income and population demand elasticities for ground- nuts and the annual percentage changes in income of consumers and population. Assuming that the income elasticity of demand for groundnuts is zero and that the population demand elasticity for groundnuts is unity, the percentage increase in demand for groundnuts in the given year will equal the annual percentage increase in popu- lation.2 The strong influence of net producer prices in neighboring countries relative to the net producer price offered by the Nigerian Marketing Boards has become evident in recent years.3 In spite of institutional obstacles and poor transportation facilities, market forces can be expected to bring about movements in the relative quantities of a crop offered for sale in the respective markets (the Nigerian domestic market, the market for smugglers and the marketing boards) in response to net producer price differ- entials. The smuggling of marketing board crops is subject to some risk (the legal status of this economic activity is still ambiguous in places). A marketing board crop will tend to be smuggled across the border so long as the expected net producer price exceeds the marketing board net producer price received by farmers, producers and middlemen, where the factors used to weight the net pro- ducer prices ruling in neighboring countries are the probability of not getting caught in the process of 104 smuggling and the probability of not getting a conviction once caught.4 It is not clear whether policy makers should drive these probabilities to zero or one. In the short run, therefore, we expect sales to the boards of any crop to be influenced by the net producer price paid by the board, the net producer price of the crop or its allied product in the Nigerian internal market, the incomes of consumers of the crop, the stock of the crop available in any given marketing period and the relative net producer price for the crop in neighboring countries--or more strictly the expected net producer prices in neighboring countries. In the long run, sales to the boards are also affected by substitutions in production in movements along given transformation curves as a result of differential rates of taxation on crops or more generally on economic activities and shifts to new transformation curves due to research etc. Farm managers will in this case not only be affected by relative expected crop prices but also relative standard deviations of prices and yields. Determinants of the level of taxes to impose will include projected revenue needs of the marketing board for its activities (of which stabilization is only one), State Government revenue for development plans, and even political considerations (the level of taxes on cocoa was a political issue in the Western State in the 1950's and the early 1960 '5) . 105 Intuitively, it would appear that the response of tax revenue from a given crop to changes in the board's producer price for this crop is somehow related to the response of sales (to the board) of this crop to changes in the board's producer price. In the case of two crops, given the same percentage change in their producer prices, it would appear that tax revenue response to this price change will be "larger" with the crop that has the "larger" response in sales (to the board) to price changes. What then is the link between the response of tax revenue from a crop to changes in the board's price (or inversely to changes in the level of taxes per ton on this crop) and the response of sales of this crop (to the board) to changes in the board's producer price? Sales to the Marketing Board and Government and Marketing Board Revenue From;the Taxation of Crops Define revenue proceeds by the State Government and its marketing board from taxes on a given crop as: R. = t.M. (1) Where Rj is total revenue from all taxation on a marketing board crop, tj is the composite unit tax and Mj is the quantity of the jth crop sold to the board. Total taxation is composed of marketing board so-called trading surplus, Produce sales tax and export tax. In such a regime of s '1. 1:011 Gas Nul- ’t) a} 5.1 II“ 106 unit taxes the elasticity of government and marketing board revenue from taxes on a crop with respect to the net producer price paid to the farmer is the sum of the unit tax elasticity with respect to the net producer price5 and the elasticity of the quantity of the crop sold to the marketing board with respect to the net producer price. If policy makers implicitly assume that prices paid to farmers exert no influence on sales of crops to the marketing board, then the revenue elasticity with respect to the net producer price equals the unit tax elasticity with respect to net producer price. Since the latter can be presumed negative as long as taxes are positive, policy makers and some academicians implicitly assume that the elasticity of government and marketing board revenue from taxes on a given crop with respect to the net producer price paid to farmers by the board is always negative (i.e., that raising net producer prices paid to farmers will always reduce government and marketing board revenues from taxes on the crop). If the elasticity of sales of a given crop to the marketing board with respect to its net producer price is negative (i.e., sales fall as farmers are offered higher prices), then the revenue elasticity with respect to net producer price is always negative which implies that government and marketing board revenues will always fall if taxes on crops are lowered or net producer prices are raised; if the elasticity 107 of sales to the marketing board with respect to net producer price is positive and is greater than the absolute value of the unit tax elasticity with respect to net producer price, then the revenue elasticity with respect to net producer price is positive, meaning that government and marketing board revenues from taxes on a crop will £i§g_when farmers are paid higher net producer prices. This possibility is potentially very significant: revenue for State Governments has become a constraining force6 in State development plans; this ability to raise State revenues from internal sources affects the overall economic and social development of the country. Higher producer prices paid to farmers benefit them on many counts: higher cash money incomes enhance the farmers' ability to invest in new and superior forms of capital (human and non-human), an investment ability that is essential to the transformation of traditional agriculture; or to create a potential market for the goods of the young but rapidly expanding industrial sector, though the importance of this depends on the percentage change in farmers' income and the income elasticity of demand for these products. Higher producer prices would slow down the artificially induced exit of resources from the farm sector as in the case of labor whose expected marginal value products on the farms are drastically lowered by heavy taxation of marketing board crops. 108 Tables 4.1 and 4.3 show the unit tax elasticities7 for cotton and groundnuts. The higher the taxes on crops the larger is the (absolute value of) elasticity. These tables form the basis for the revenue elasticity tables. It is to be expected that if taxes on a crop are very heavy and sales of this crop to the board are price responsive, sales will fall and government revenues will also fall. If sales are indeed very price responsive, it is possible that increases in producer prices paid to farmers will induce large increments in sales and possibly lead to a rise in (crop) tax revenue. This indeed seems to be the case for the levels of taxes imposed on cotton and groundnuts for the period 1950-66, as shown in Tables 4.2 and 4.4. It has been shown (footnote 4) that the elasticity of government and marketing board revenue (from taxes on a crop) with respect to the crop net producer price paid by the board to farmers is the sum of the unit tax price elasticity (E ) and the elasticity t.P j n of sales of the crop with respect to the net producer price of the crop paid by the board (E ). Under the Man assumptions (stated on page 100) above, the unit tax price elasticities are presented in Tables 4.1 and 4.3 for cotton and groundnuts. To get the elasticity of government and marketing board revenue (from taxes on a crop), i.e., ER P , we assume different values for the elasticity of ' n 3 sales of the crop with respect to the net producer price 109 TABLE 4.l.--Unit Tax Elasticities for Cotton Using Producer Prices, Taxes and Potential Producer Price, Nigeria, 1950-1966. Potential Unit Cotton Producer Tax Year Prices Taxes Price Elasticities Pn tj Pp aN/Ton 1950 36.37 36.04 72.77 -l.01 1951 55.07 58.04 113.11 -0.95 1952 55.07 29.50 84.57 -1.87 1953 54.81 43.30 98.11 -l.27 1954 55.10 24.30 79.40 -2.27 1955 54.68 27.00 81.68 -2.03 1956 55.13 17.10 72.23 -3.22 1957 54.88 14.10 68.98 -3.89 1958 54.91 -0.04 54.87 1372.75 1959 55.07 -2.60 54.47 21.18 1960 55.07 -2.00 53.07 27.53 1961 46.67 .004 46.674 -ll66.75 1962 45.27 4.70 49.97 -9.63 1963 45.27 6.90 52.17 -6.56 1964 46.67 11.20 57.87 -4.17 1965 46.67 7.60 54.27 -6.14 1966 44.80 -l.30 53.50 -34.46 Source: Producer Prices, 1950-1959, Extended and amended Kriesel Series: H- Kriesel, Cotton Marketigg in Nigeria, CSNRD-24, p. 73. The price series 1960-1966 are our own constructed series resulting from our dissatisfaction with existing series. Helleiner's Table 11-8-6 (pp. 474-475) usod only Grade 1 prices for all the years when a weighted price index of prices is cloarly better. However, constructing a weighted price index faces many problems. For weights for the price series 1960-1967, see H. Kriesel, Cotton Marketing in Nigeria, CSNRD-24, p. 55; for net prices after deduction of produce sales tax for different grades of cotton for 1960-67, sec M. o. Titiloye and A. A. Ismail, §;Survey of the Trends and Problems in 322:00mestic Arrangements for the Marketipg of Groundnuts and Cotton, International Conference on the Marketing Board System, NISER, Ibadan, 1971, pp. 78-80. Prices for different grades of cotton 1968-71 from Report of the Study Group on Cotton 59d Other Fabrics, National Agricultural Development Committee, Federal Department of Agriculture, Lapos, 1971, p. 7; weights for prices of different grades 1968-70 from moan weights in above Report of . . ., p. 60 while weights for 1971-72 were assumed to be those of 1970—71. Note: The unit tax elasticity is defined as the percentage change in taxes per unit of a marketing board crop per unit porosntago change in the not producer price of the crop paid by the marketing board (exact formula derived in footnote 4--the negative of the not producer price divided by the composite tax per unit of the crop). Thus, the unit tax elasticity is negative as long as taxes are positive (no subsidies). The higher the not producer prices (Pn) relative to those taxes (t) the larger the (absolute) value of this elasticity. 110 .eoaum neocooum uec e.oueon on» O» uuemneu new: canon ecu on common uo modem mo unwoauneao ecu can: eeneeuocw meowum Hoosooum magmas“ no huwawnwmnom ecu .Hm>ea xeu co>wm s mom .couwoo uOu modem nauseous use n.0ueon on» ca emceno omeucmuuom eco e Ham msce>eu use was» an euceco emeuceuuom ecu me pocmueo an .cm.mm .couuoo MOM modem mooscoum um: n.0uson ecu on uwwmnou nun: coupon so none» Bonn nwace>om venom mcwuexuex use ucmscue>ou emueum cuecuuoz no huaoduaeam e59 .H.v manna eouu cm.ua "ouoz .H.v canes an as seen nous» .meOMum couuou "ouusom nv.n~- nv.Hn- ne.~n- n..mm- n..vnu n¢.nnu n..wnu on.mu an... noon 4H.H- «n.a- .H.¢- va.nn «n.a- hd.pu ea.nu on.p an.nv nnnn mn.o 5H.H- ”n.a- an.n- an..- 5H.nu 5H.¢u °N.HH nn.nv eons nn.~- nn.m- nn..- nn.nn nn.nu nn.nu nn.nu an.o su.nv nnnn no..- nn.nu nn.as «n.a- nn.nu nn.ann no.na oa.¢ bu.n. «non nn.nnnau na.mnHH- na.vnHHu nh.nnaau np.nnmnn ns.pnsnu na.nnnnn vo°.o an.nq nnnn nn.nn nn.on nn.n~ nn.n~ nn.>~ nn.n~ mn.h~ oo.u- no.nn onnn nH.na on..~. na.n~ na.- on.a~ na.cu «n.au on.nu no.nn nnna nn.pann ns.nann nn.eann ne.nnnn np.~snm nn.n»nn nh.~ann vo.au an.qn onus an.” no.o- no.n- an.~u no.nu no..- nn.nu on.¢n an..n snag ne.a -.ou «n.a- «~.~- -.nu -..n «n.a- on.hn na.nn nnnn an.” en. no.ou no.nu no.~u no.nu no.~u oo.pu on.vn nnnn ms.“ nu. n~.on a~.au a~.~- n~.nu p~.~u on..~ oH.nn ennn ma.n ne.n me. p~.o- ~N.H- n~.~- s~.H- on.nv an.vn «nan nH.n MH.H ma. an.ou an.H- an.~- pn.nu on.n~ no.nn «nan no.4 no.~ no.” no. nn.ou nn.nu nn.ou ec.an nc.nn Anna na.n an.” an. Ho.on mo.nn Ho.~u Ho.nn vn.nn pn.nm anon 60 m I M I N I H I O I H I l .H.\2fl c n c n c n c n c w c a c n n» on a an a mu m an a mm a an a as a an new» eoxea noowum uceueuwwo haw noauwoauneau occu>om xea couuou .nnnnuonnn .onuomnz .uouaun cumauuoz .uunon «a» 0» ocean no nonununuuonm OUflHm ”Oman: Ugufluwfin HON GOUUOU HO OOfiHm H005muOHm n.6u08 Gnu Ou Hoamflfi 5%! IfldflfluuuudHfl 05G0>0¢ Run. «GOHHOUII.N.C an. lll fmxBLE 4.3.--Unit Tax Elasticities for Groundnuts Using Producer Prices, Taxes and Potential Producer Price, Nigeria, 1952-1964. Potential Producer Composite Producer Unit Tax Year' Prices Taxes Price Elasticities P t. P n J P bN/Ton 1952 35.0 20.1 55.1 —1.741 1953 35.5 16.3 51.8 -2.177 1954 35.4 5.9 41.3 -6.000 1955 32.4 8.6 41.0 -3.767 1956 37.4 15.8 53.2 -2.367 1957 33.9 -1.7 32.2 19.941 1958 36.4 2.8 39.2 -13.000 1959 37.4 8.2 45.6 -4.560 1960 33.7 4.8 38.5 -7.020 1961 30.3 4.4 34.7 -6.886 1962 30.3 6.2 36.5 —4.887 1963 32.7 8.9 41.6 -3.674 1964 34.1 9.3 43.4 -3.666 Source: Producer Prices 1950-63, Helleiner, op. cit., Table ll-B-4; 1964-65, Report of the Studngropppon Groundnuts, Federal Department of Agriculture, Lagos, 1971, p. 6. Tax figures from H. C. Kriesel, Marketing of Groundnuts in Nigeria, CSNRD-19, Michigan State University, East Lansing, 1968, Table 14, p. 68. Note: The unit tax elasticity is defined as the percentage change in taxes per unit of a marketing board crop per unit percentage change in the net producer price of the crop paid by the marketing board (exact formula derived in footnote 4--the negative of the net producer price divided by the composite tax per unit of the crop). Thus, the unit tax elasticity is negative as long as taxes are positive (no subsidies). The higher the net producer prices (Pn) relative to these taxes (t) the larger the (absolute) value of this elasticity. 1.1“2 : n .N - gamma non nn~.o n genes can H u amaze you Hon.ou I m.mm .mmma cw cou\H.o~ 2m uo muscocsoum co nosey enmeomeou nun: ..u.e .euscocsOum no munuwueeae eowum mouse on» sun: eeueeuoca eeonun mesons eueaueu acumen ma esce>eu vueon unauoxuss use ucoe=u0>om ocweeeuocn no >uwaanneeoa on» .euscvcsoum co nexeu no ae>ea ce>qu now so: eoauoz .OUmua headache uec e.oweon ecu ou avenues can: oneon ecu on euncocsoum uo eeaee no auwuaueeae on» sun: eeeeeuosa eouum nauseoun memeaeu an esco>eu can» mannweu uo mumawnwuaom ecu .He>ea xeu ce>am e mom .auscucdouo wow enema ueosooum uec e.oueon on» c« emcenu eueuceuuem eco a now esce>ou menu cw eoceno emeuceouem on» as oesdueo ed euscocfiouo now euawm noose um 90: e.oueon ecu o» uuemeeu can: successouu co nexeu souu neoce>em venom mcwuexue: use unsecue>oo aeueum chocuuoz no madame-eds one .n.v easea see .cm um you aeuoz .o .m .usma .eomem .ewsuanowumc uo uceauuemea aeueoem .eouuwfifioo acoamoae>eo ouo vsum ecu uo an em .mooauvoma .vumuaa vanes ..unu .mo .uocweaaom "momHIOan even neuaum someone «eonsom Heunuasuaumd Hecoauez .euscocsouo co enn.~ vnm.o noo.n- non.~- non.nu non.v- non.n- n.m n.vn «and can." nun.o can.su ven.~- can.nu can..- .56."- n.o n.an mend nnm.a enm.on enm.n- nmn.nu amm.e- nan.n- amn.vu «.n n.on «can nnn.o- new.«. one..- nma.nu nmo.nn omn.a- nmm.n- v.v n.on Hons ouo.nu omo.n- o~o.n- o~o.nu o~o.r- oao.o- oao.nu o.v a.nn coma ovo.~ onn.ou onn.~- onn.n- onn.vu own.n- onn.vn «.n v.5n nnna ooo.hu ooo.au ooo.nmu ooo.~«- ooo.nm- ooo.va- ooo.nn- o.« v.nn «nan Hen.n~ an.n~ Hem.n~ Hen.o~ men.ns Hem.nm Hen.ma n.a- n.nn snag nnn.n nnn.n ann.o- soM.H- enn.~- ann.n. snn.«n n.nm v.5n anon "an." nn~.o hoe.au nnh.~- ene.nu an“..- sne.n- o.n v.~n nnma . . ooo.«- ooo.v- ooo.nu ooo.o- ooo.~- ooo.n- n.n ¢.nn vnnn nuo.n nan.H sen.on ahn.n- epn.~u aen.n- apn.~u n.an n.nn nnnn nn~.e nnu.n nnn.o nvp.ou HvF.H- th.n- «vs.nu n.o~ o.nn «non v n N u a n o n n- u eosxza c n a n a n a n a n c n a n “a as a an a an a an a re a xm a am a an sexes eoowum use» uceueuuwo Hen mequuuaueeam esce>ez mes assessouo .vomnuanoa .anuumnz .nou-un :uoauuoz .eneom oau 0» eeHem uo eewuaowueeau eouum assume: uceueuuwn Now sound moostum n.0ueom mcwuexue: ecu ou uoemmem nun: meauauwueeam esce>um xee “euncvcsououn.e.e mange 113 of the crop paid by the board (E ). The assumed values M.P j n for EM.P are -1,0,1,2,3,4,5,6. From the calculated Et.P J n j n and the assumed values for EM P , ER P is calculated for j n j n 1950-66. From Tables 4.2 and 4.4, the possibility of increasing tax revenue from a crop for given levels of taxes increases with the elasticity of sales of the crop to the board with respect to the net producer price paid by the board. This possibility increases with the level of taxes, i.e., for given sales elasticity of the crop with respect to its net producer price, the elasticity of tax revenue from a crOp with respect to the net producer price it pays to farmers increases in numerical value with the level of taxes.8 From Table 4.2, in 1952, composite tax on cotton was LN 29.50 per ton and with a sales price elasticity of cotton = 2, E = 0.13; in 1953, the R.P 3 n composite tax was LN 43.30/ton and with the same sales price elasticity, ER P = 0.73. Allowing only the unit j n tax elasticity to vary and setting E = 1, the corre— M.P J sponding figures are: for 1952, ER.P -0.87; for 1953 3 n ER P = -0.27. Thus as taxes on marketing board crops rise, j n the responsiveness of (crop) tax revenue to changes in net ":3 producer price also rises and conversely for a fall. Resource Fixipy, Supplpresponse and Government Revenue If relative crop price changes in a given crop enterprise are such that the expected MVP's of resources 114 are bounded by the salvage values and acquisition values of these resources so that there is no motivation for investment or disinvestment in these resources, the crop supply (output) response to crop price changes will be small. Building on the recognition that a durable resource has two prices, the Johnsonian theory leads us to expect, in principle, a difference between expansion as... s and contraction supply price elasticities corresponding, respectively, to the rising and falling phases of crop prices.9 Even though sales to the marketing board are of Elrdnary interest for (crop) tax revenue purposes, insofar as; we can presume positive correlation between total out- EDtrt and sales to the board, we would still be interested .ir1 the underlying production relations as such. Starting from a production function, we can write the output (supply) price elasticity of a crop as the w€Eighted sum of elasticities of demand for the productive reisources with respect to the crop price where the weights Eilrea the output elasticities of these resources. From tzk1£is, the more resources whose demands (and supplies of t153€3d quantities on hand) are not affected by crop price Cibiéinges, then the less likely it is that the supply of tlrlee crOp will be affected by crop price changes. In EtcIiCiition, for this to be strictly true, it must also not pay to change resource service flows per unit of stock or 115 per unit of stock per unit of time through variations in the rates of utilization of the durable resources. Implied in the above is the following. The link between the investment and disinvestment response of durable resources to crop price changes and the supply price response of crops would seem to be influenced in some way by the "importance" of the resources in pro- duction. If it does not pay to invest or disinvest in some durable resources that are relatively unimportant in the production of this crop but it pays to invest or disinvest in a resource whose "importance" in the pro- duction of this crop far outweighs these other resources, then we may observe significant output response to crop price changes on account of changes in this resource even though it does not pay to invest or disinvest or vary the rates of utilization of the other resources.10 The higher the output elasticity of a resource, the stronger the link between its investment and disinvestment response to crop price changes and the supply price response of the crop and vice versa. Under competition, the larger the factor income shares of resources, the stronger the influence of the factor's investment and investment response to crop price changes on the output supply (price) relations of the crop.11 Irreversibilities in the crop supply relation derivable from irreversibilities in the investment- disinvestment relations in productive facilities may enable 116 governments and marketing boards to maintain higher tax rates on a given crop than would otherwise be the case in the absence of these irreversibilities. The extent of these irreversibilities will to some extent be influenced by the ease of substitution of resources among enter- prises. For example, let the acquisition price of a farmer of a given farming skill and age be what it would cost a farm-firm to "acquire" a new farmer of the same vintage now. This is the supply price of a farmer of this vintage. Let his salvage value be approximated by the present value of the net income streams that he would earn in the next best alternative use. If government and marketing board taxes are such that the MVP's of resources (labor and land) are bounded by their off-farm market acquisition prices and salvage values, where the relevant salvage value is still within the farm sector, then government and marketing board taxes induce farm reorgani- zation that still leaves most of these resources within the farm sector--a farmer may reorganize and quit groundnut production in favor of food production as a result of government pricing policy.12 If resources are not enter- prise specific, then the degree of resource fixity within a given crop enterprise may be much less than that for the farm sector as a whole. 117 These propositions may then be derived: from our aprior knowledge of the limited degree of resource fixity within crop enterprises, and the transformation possi— bilities between crops in the cotton-groundnut-foods economy of the Northern States, the long~run revenue potential from taxing any of these crops is not very great. Second, given the much larger degree of resource fixity within the agricultural sector vis-a-vis the non— agricultural sector, there is some potential for revenue from the agricultural sector as a whole given existing demand functions for resources now in agriculture for use in the non-agricultural sector. Public policies such as minimum wage laws for unskilled workers in the urban areas effectively raise the off-farm salvage value of people currently engaged in the farm sector. Such policies have the effect of making resources variable that might have otherwise been fixed in the farm sector. Thus, if there are substantial irreversibilitiesl3 in the investment- disinvestment relations and in the output supply relation in the agricultural sector as a whole, then there is some potential for a tax on the agricultural sector. This is the theoretical link between irreversibilities in the investment-disinvestment relations as defined by Johnson and problems of government and marketing board revenue and supply response in developing agriculture. To the extent that irreversibilities in the investment-disinvestment 118 relations and in the output supply relation are small when the agricultural sector as a whole is considered, then the revenue potential is small. If demand schedules for resources (now in agriculture) for use in the non- agricultural sector should shift rightwards for given (upward sloping) supply curves of these resources, then the salvage values of these resources in the non- agricultural sector will rise and any government and marketing board taxation which depresses the MVP's of these resources below their non-agricultural sector salvage values will lead to disinvestment in these resources, the mobility of these resources from the agri- cultural sector to the non-agricultural sector, and a likely fall in agricultural output. From our apriori knowledge of the extent of the mobility of resources between crOp enterprises in the cotton-groundnuts-food crops economy of the Northern States, we suspect that irreversibilities in the investment- disinvestment relations underlying the production of any one of these crops (though not necessarily within the farm sector as a whole) may not be extensive. Summary and Conclusions It has been shown in this chapter that for purposes of government and marketing board revenues from taxes on crops, the relevant variable is the sales and not the total output of the crop (arguments are provided to show 119 why we cannot apriori presume that the correlation coefficient between total output and sales to the board is unity for any marketing board crop in Nigeria).14 Various influences on sales of marketing board crops are discussed. This discussion underlies the estimation effort in the next chapter. Policy makers and some academicians are concerned about the effects of changes in the net producer prices the boards pay farmers on State Government revenues, with the usual presumption that paying farmers higher prices will always lead to a fall in State Government revenues from taxes on these crops. A simple model is presented to show the dependence of the responsiveness of (crop) tax revenues on the price responsiveness of sales of crops to the board, particularly when these crops have large domestic and neighboring-country markets. Some illustrative calculations are used with empirical data on level of taxes and net producer prices for cotton and groundnuts for the period 1950-66 to show how tax revenues from these two crops would fall if net producer prices paid to farmers were further reduced (and thus implied taxes raised) for reasonably low elasticities of sales of these crops to the board with respect to the net producer prices paid by the board. These calculations illustrate the eventual futility of heavy taxes on these crops with respect to raising large crop tax revenues. 120 The last part of this chapter showed that questions of the revenue potential of individual crops and the farm sector as a whole depend on the underlying investment- disinvestment process and its responsiveness to various relative price changes. The calculations of the government and marketing board revenue elasticities with respect to both net producer price and taxes in this chapter clearly point to the relation of (crop) tax revenue to the price responsive- ness of sales of cr0ps to the marketing board. In the next chapter, this price responsiveness of sales of crops to the marketing boards is estimated. FOOTNOTES 1" . . . Palm oil is available for export only in insignificant quantities . . . this could be due to increased demand for food. " See Twelfth Annual Report of the Western Nigeria Marketing Board, 1966, p. 7. In its report a yearlater, the WNMB stated "The abnormal fall in the quantity of palm produce purchased in the period was due to the immediate effect of the Nigerian crisis. More- over, domestic sales yielded higheryprices_per ton than overseas sales for the farmer or the producerllicensed buy1ng agent like the Western Niger1a Development Corpo- rat1on (emphas1s my own). See Thirteenth Annual Re ort of the Western Nigeria Marketing Board, 1967, pp. 6- g. A correspondent for the Dail Times writes of groundnut oil, "What used to cost 1793 a Bottle now costs 5/= . . ." See Daily Times, Lagos, February 3, 1972, p. 7. 2Assuming groundnut consumer prices are constant between two years and making groundnut consumption (C) a function of population (P) and measured income (Y), then even if the income elasticity of demand for groundnuts were zero and the population elasticity of demand for groundnuts were unity, the percentage increase in domestic groundnut consumption over the period will equal the percentage increase in population: C = C(Y,P) from which A—C..= .A—Y—+n AP C ncy Y cp P where AC is the percentage increase in groundnut con- sumption over the period, “c is the income elasticity of consumption of groundnuts, ncp is the population elasticity of demand for groundnuts. Setting "cy = 0 and ”cp = 1 makes AC _ AP. 2:"?- 121 122 3A writer in West Africa writes "Available supplies to the marketing board have in any case been reduced because of the continuance of smuggling over the border into Niger, which has been encouraged by the high prices obtainable for groundnuts in that country. At the same time in Nigeria, in the bush itself, it is believed that larger quantities are being_pressed for oil for domestic consum t1onfi—(empha51s my own). See West Africa, London, 52857, March 17, 1972. ‘— 4For the last groundnut season, "Farmers were getting about LN 86 a ton on the border with Niger Republic compared with SN 36 which they get in Nigeria." See Daily Times, Lagos, February 3, 1972, p. 7. 5The sum of the three components of the tax per unit of the crop when added to the net producer price paid to farmers by the marketing boards (Pn) gives the potential producer price (Pp ) that the farmer would have received per unit of the crop in the absence of all State government and marketing board taxation. Thus the derived value of the unit tax on a crop depends on the net producer price per unit of the crop that the marketing board decides to pay the farmers. we can then write: tj = f(Pn,Pp), or more specifically, tj = Pp - Pn' Differentiating (3) with respect to Pn and converting to elasticities, then: ERan = Etan + EMan P t. t.-P _-Ep__-Lp-1]_12 . where Etan - tj — tj — tj < 0, 1f tj < Pp and ER pn is the State Government and marketing board revenue elasticity with respect to the net producer price paid out by the board, Etjpn is the unit tax ela ticity with respect to net producer price and E (_ a—in Pn Man Pn M is the elasticity of sales to the marketing board witg) respect to the net producer price. Alternatively, suppose we write: . = P - P t] P n . ..=P- M. P.-PM. R3 tJMJ ( P Pn) 3 PM] n J 123 dR dM dP dM P=PpP+d93 [Mj+P3_lP] n n dR. P dM. P M. M.P dM. P E¥=dep Mg-(P-P)M.-[Pr-IP)M.+Pn Pugh-Pm. n J n J P 3 P n J P n J _ -22. —EM.P t. J n 3 But from t. = P - Pn, and assuming that P does not change, 3 p p ..22 Et.P " t~ J n J => ER.P = EM.P + Et.P wh1ch 15 the same as 1n 3 n 3 n 3 n the text. 6 In the 1972-73 Federal Budget, of the expected gross revenue of LN 650 m., about LN 180 m. will be allo- cated to State Governments and LN 160 m. will be set aside for the development fund. The Federal Government is repaying immediately the LN 5.5 m. loan given by the (then) Regional Marketing Boards to the former Central government in 1964. It is hoped that early repayment will help the marketing boards and state governments to stabilize their finances and pay higher producer prices. See West Africa, #2861 (April 14, 1972), pp. 439, 465. In the - Federal Budget, projected Total Revenue was LN 152 mill, of which LN 54 mill was to be appropriated to the States. The corresponding figures for 1969-70 were, respectively, LN 188 mill, LN 73 mill, and for 1970-71, LN 279 mill, LN 115 mill respectively. Source for these figures: Annual Economic ReviewL Nigeria (London: Standard Bank Ltd., 1968, 1970). 7The unit tax elasticity is not derived from any choice--theoretic framework of an optimizing economic agent. It is based more on definition of the tax per unit of the crop being expressed as the difference between the potential producer price and the net producer price per unit of the crop after all taxes have been deducted. Roughly speaking, this elasticity indicates the "required" 124 change in taxes if net producer prices paid to farmers are changed--if prices are lowered, by definition, implied taxes are raised, hence the negative elasticity. 8This is consistent with the expectations of the Model: From footnote 4, 9Glenn L. Johnson, "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis," Journal of Farm Economics (May, 1960). 10Second order effects such as the effect of the increase in the "important" resource on the marginal products of resources with which it is complementary need to be incorporated in a full analysis. 11Fortunately, empirical investigations of the link between the investment-disinvestment relations in durable resources and the output supply relation have focused on resources whose factor shares loom large in the production process. See Glenn L. Johnson, Overproduction Trap (The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1972). 12Given a transformation curve between, say, guinea corn and groundnuts, government and marketing board taxation of groundnuts may so change relative crop prices as to produce a corner solution in which the farmer after reorganization produces only guinea corn. Allocation of the fixed resources is then based on their on-farm opportunity costs. l3Bauer recognizes this point. He states, "the presence of certain irreversible functional relationships on the side of both production and consumption may also be turned to good use in the framing of taxation. Though very high prices may at times be required to stimulate the establishment of productive capacity for certain crops, once the capacity has been established, it may continue to be operated at appreciably low prices; the establishment 125 of plantations (both estates and small holdings) of cultivated crops in remote areas and their subsequent operation are a convenient example." See P. T. Bauer, Economic Analysis and Policy in Underdeveloped Countries, Cambridge University Press, London, 1957, p. 95. Bauer however, does not provide any theory to explain these irreversibilities. 14Using seed issues and assuming different seed- rate applications per acre and different yields per acre, we have estimated total output of seed cotton for all the Northern States for the period 1960/61-1970/71. For some reason, the correlation coefficient between sales of seed cotton to the marketing board and various estimates of total output of seed cotton in the Northern States over this period was found to be negative in all cases. For all estimates of total output the correlation coefficient ‘was approximately -0.26. Probably this has something to do with our estimates of output. CHAPTER V ESTIMATION OF IMPACT ON GOVERNMENT AND MARKETING BOARD TAX REVENUE FROM GROUNDNUTS AND COTTON OF CHANGES IN THE BOARD'S NET PRODUCER PRICES FOR THESE CROPS Introduction The last chapter dealt with the relationship laetween (crop) tax revenue responsiveness to changes in 'the board's producer price and the responsiveness of sales (to the board) to producer price changes. Estimation of tflie sales price responsiveness of marketing board crops is; essential for a quantitative assessment of the effect (crop) tax revenue of paying farmers higher producer cum This chapter attempts to estimate Prices for these crops. t1'lis sales price responsiveness and to assess the quanti- tative impact on (crop) tax revenue of changes in the board's producer prices. This chapter is divided into four main sections. .1115? first part sketches a simultaneous equation system in vvrlidzh.we incorporate our apriori knowledge of the factors influencing the sale of a crop to the marketing board. The 126 127 essence of this is the need to identify and specify a structure of which the sales supply equation is only a component. The second part of the chapter contains a modified model in which all the regressors of the sales supply equation are predetermined. Single sales supply equations are then estimated for both cotton and groundnuts by ordinary least squares. The third section contains equations to predict sales when farmers are paid higher prices. These predictions, together with the new higher producer prices and the implied lower taxes on farmers, are then used to assess the quantitative impact of higher ‘producer prices on tax revenue from these two crops. The last section of the chapter contains a summary c>f our findings in this chapter. The simultaneous equation nature of the problem “was recognized in Chapter IV. It is assumed that the -féirmers, producers, and middlemen of any marketing board (3113p allocate total output of the crop between domestic nCurl-industrial consumption requirements (farm and non- farm) and sales to the board. It is also assumed that prOducers for any marketing board in Nigeria face an infinitely elastic demand curve at the price set by the board 128 The Model The structural equations of the model are postu- lated to be: D. J u o 75 I): domestic consumption demand; D.’ 3 J = Mj(Yj, PN , PD ): sales to the marketing board j j = Y.(PN , PN , K)- supply relation; 3 r = Yj - 0.: marketing board crop supply identity is domestic consumption demand for the marketing board crop by both the farming and non-farming population, assumed endogenous: is the domestic producer price of the marketing board crop, assumed endogenous; is real income of all domestic consumers of this crop, assumed exogenous; is the quantity of the crop sold to the marketing board in any given year, assumed endogenous; is the total output of the crop in a given year, assumed endogenous; is the net producer price of the crop exogenously fixed by the board which determines the infinitely elastic demand curve facing the farmers, producers, and middlemen of this marketing board crop; 129 P is the net producer price of a closely competitive crop (i.e., competitive in production). We assume that the price of this crop is exogenously determined outside this system; K is the set of exogenous factors affecting production (weather, new production functions from application of fertilizer, spraying, and seed dressing, etc.); in this study, this set is specifically represented by time. The crop supply identity says that total output is allocated between non-industrial domestic consumption (farm and non-farm) and sales to the marketing board.1 {The endogenous variables of the system then are Dj' PD , j Y’ Mj while the exogenous variables are PNj' I, K, and j' PMQr‘ If we give the above structural equations their llidiear approximations, we have D - ‘ " - = 3 1: OLD (1ka 0:2 It alt (la) ”4- -Bo-B P - 81> -B Y. = 5 (1b) 3t 1 th 2 Djt 3 3t 2t jt F w° ' m1Pth: ' wZPNrt ' (”3Kt = E:31: (1C) gjt; ‘ Y. i-D = o ,t:= 1,...,11 (1d) Vv - . . . hlch can be written 1n matrix form as BYt + I‘xt = st (1) g: 1.5: nicer-was“... ~ 130 where: r 7 1 1 —a1 0 0 ~ FDjt B = 0 -82 1 -B3 ; Yt = PDjt O 0 0 1 th l 0 1 -1 L J y. -JtJ 1‘ = E7 ._ ‘1' = 3 = no a2 0 0 0 r Xt [1 ' 8t Feltj -80 0 -81 0 0 It EZt -wo 0 -w1 -w2 -w3 Pde €3t Lo 0 o o o 3 P L0 A r LKt 1 where we assume that the disturbances of the structural equations satisfy the assumptions of the classical normal linear regression model which in matrix notation are: at ~ N(O,¢) E(ete;) = 0 Wherfi ¢ is the variance-covariance matrix of the structural disturbances . 2 By the order conditions for identifiability3 we have time following results: the equation for the domestic COnSUHEJtion demand of the marketing board crop (1a) With two endoqenous variables and two excluded predetermined vari‘E‘bles is over-identified; the equation for the sale C) f a Ornap to the marketing board (lb) with three endogenous ¥ 131 variables and two excluded predetermined variables is exactlygidentified, while the equation depicting the supply relation (10) with one endogenous variable and one excluded predetermined variable is under-identified. The equation of most interest to us is that depitxing sales of the crop to the marketing board (lb), the: sales supply equation. For the rank and order con- ditjxans for identifiability of this equation, form the system matrix: ‘1 -al 0 0 -ao —dz 0 O 0 (Bpl‘) = 0 -82 1 -B3 -80 0 -81 0 0 0 O 0 1 -wo 0 -w1 —w2 -w3 L1 0 1 -1 o o o o o 3 The :submatrix obtained by striking out the second row and all (columns of (B,F) corresponding to variables that are ificllnded in the sales supply equation is: 1 ['1 -a2 0 o A = z - _ ,0 0 wz m3 51 0 o 03 By the .rank criterion, the sales supply equation is exactly ldentified or over-identified if and only if rank (A) = (3‘1 where G is the number of structural equations. A has a. . . t leasrt one 3X3 non31ngular square submatrix (A*)- 132 {'1 -a0 41% _ I _ . _ _ . A* — 50 w 0 , IA*I — azwo, h. 0 0] so that rank (A) = 3 = G-l which,4 together with the order condition above, provides the necessary and sufficient condition for identification of the sales supply equation.5 The reduced form equations can then be written in unrestricted form as: Yt = th + Vt (2) Ir 1 P ' ‘ ' 1 Djt H11 H12 H13 H11 1 v1t Y = , = = a t PD3t ' Ht H21 H22 H23 H24 ' xt It ' Vt Vzt M. n n n n v 3t 31 32 33 34 Pth ‘ 3t y. n n n n iY (_gtj _41 42 43 43 _kt J 4g FIOHI (1) Y can be solved- Y = -B~1FX + 8.18 (3) ' t ° t t t and from (2) above, (3) WOUld imply _ _ -1 Ht_BI‘ _-1 Vt‘B at from Which the variance-covariance matrix of the reduced form d i sturbances is l w == E(VtV£) = E[(B’ at) (B_let)’] 9:-» ‘. '5 ““‘WJV 133 where w, being a linear conbination of the structural disturbances, is assumed to obey normal classical linear I . 6 regre331on assumptions. , B2 ”“1 0‘1"‘3‘183 0‘11 l = -1 -1 1-8 1 al+32 3 -82 a1 82+a183 82 L0 0 82+a1 0‘ From _ _ -1 -1 Yt _ B F Xt + B at, F ‘1 "'_ _ __ __ . - .— Dj a082+a18b w0a1(1 83) a282 a181 alw1(l 83) p . 1 a +8 -w (1-8 ) a 8 -w (1—8 ) 03 = - o o o 3 2 1 1 3 al+gz Mj o‘082"°‘1Bo"*’o(82"0‘1‘33) “282 ’0181‘w1(82+3183) ij L-wo(82+a1) o -w1(82+a1) -w2a1(1-B3) -w3al(l-B3)q F1 I —w2(1-83) -w3(l-B3) t Pth -w2(82+a183) -w3(82+a183) - (B +a ) -w (B +a ) iLKt J “2 2 1 3 2 1 .1 134 - _ _ . P 1 B2 “1 “1 “153 “1 8it + 1 a1+32 -l -1 1-83 1 €2t '82 “1 B2 +“183 82 83t L0 0 82 +011 OJ b0 J Thus the endogenous variables are expressed in terms of all the predetermined variables and the structural disturbances. We would then estimate the sales supply equation by two stage least squares. Two stage least squares estimation of the sales supply equation would require prior (first stage) esti- mation of domestic price and total output of the marketing board crop, the other endogenous variables in the sales supply equation. As we have no figures on total output of groundnuts and cotton over the last two decades,7 we cannot estimate the sales supply relation in this model; as data becomes available in the future, this equation could be estimated within the context of this model. For ordinary least squares estimation, we would need to operationalize the model so that the OLS estimates will be unbiased and consistent. 135 A Modified Model We shall assume that the only price affecting the quantities of any crop sold to the board are the board's net producer prices.8 We would expect that the higher this price, the less will be consumed on the domestic market and the more that would be sold to the board. It is also assumed that Nigerian farmers are unaware of the true world prices for their products and that the price affecting their production and sales decisions is the board's net producer price. Short Run Modified Model The short run here is a given production-marketing period, strictly speaking, a given marketing period, when the total quantity of output from production of cotton or groundnuts is fixed. The aggregate sales supply curve of a crop to the board in this case of a partial monopsony on the buying side is the difference between this available total stock of the crop and the lateral sum of all indi- vidual (domestic: farmers and non—farmers) demand curves for the crop as shown on the following page, using ground- nuts for illustration: Sijyj is the given stock of ground- nuts within this period (zero price elasticity of supply or production); CjCj is the lateral sum of all domestic demand curves for groundnuts; Smj is the lateral difference between total supply and total consumption; P . is the net NJ producer price for groundnuts offered by the board, which I l l I I | I | 5? l ' l l l | l i ' ' s 11 0 Me M, 2: I Co (:50ij in equilibrium is assumed equal to the appropriately adjusted home market price. With the demand curve CjCj and a marketing board price of PNj' OCo is consumed and OMo is sold to the marketing board. With a higher marketing ; Nj' marketing board.9 From the diagram, board price P CO1 is consumed and OM1 is sold to the 10 the elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the marketing board with respect to the net producer price paid by the board is positive so long as the elasticity of total output (supply) of the crop with respect to this net producer price is non- negative and the (money income constant) price elasticity of demand for groundnuts is negative. Under normal 137 circumstances we expect these conditions to hold for most marketing board crOps. We assume that the real income (I) of the bulk of domestic consumers of groundnuts is not influenced by the sales of groundnuts to the marketing 11 The producers themselves form a small proportion board. of domestic consumers of groundnuts. An increase in real income leads to a rightward and upward shift in the aggregate demand curve and a corresponding upward and leftward shift in the sales supply curve if groundnuts are a normal good while the converse result holds if groundnuts are inferior goods. In the latter case, an increase in real income of consumers leads to a downward and leftward shift in the aggregate demand curve to CECE and a corre- sponding rightward and downward shift in the sales supply curve to SMjSMj' Thus if the sales supply function is M). = Mijj, I, yj) , (4) the plausible signs of the partials of the function are: 3M. > < I < 0 as nch > 0 3M 8M. 5'19.) 0' Y Nj > 0, j where Yj is the given stock of the marketing board crop and n is the income elasticity of demand for this crop. ch All the explanatory variables in the above relation are assumed predetermined so that when given a specific regression expression, the disturbances and the explanatory 138 variables are presummed to be independently distributed; hence we can expect the OLS estimates to be unbiased and consistent. The Long Run Modified Model If the period is long enough for production to respond to price and other variables, then changes in sales of groundnuts to the marketing board would then partly reflect substitutions in production as producers move along given or changing transformation surfaces in response to relative price changes. For these long run relations, theory leads us to expect some irreversibilities in the underlying investment-disinvestment relationships. Then the output response of Nigerian farmers depend not only on the magnitude of the crop price change but also on the sign of the price change.12 The theory of the investment- disinvestment response to crop price changes (see Chapters III and IV) leads us to expect a difference between expansion supply price elasticities and contraction supply price elasticities corresponding to the expansion and contraction phases of crop prices respectively. These elasticities are also influenced by the most recent history of relative prices and farmers' expectations about their movement in the immediate future. In the diagram on the following page, if expected food prices rise relative to the price of a marketing board crop, then with food crops competing with the marketing board crop in production the 139 25A c. J K5////////1 5»; l SW, ' 533‘ C l 5 l J 1 fl. I > M." 9' supply curve of the latter sh1fts from Sonsto to Slestl and the sales supply curve, for g1ven demand curves, correspondingly shifts upwards and to the left, to S’.S’ In this case, an increase in food prices leads M3 M)” to a fall in total sales to the marketing board from Mjo to Mjl' From the above discussion, we would have a supply relation S . = S .(P Y3 Y3 K) (5) Nj' Nr' and 2gljao,;TS:,-Y-j-o Nj Nr 140 where PNr is the price of a competing crop and K stands for those exogenous factors like technical change which influence total Supply of the marketing board crop. Empirical Results The sales supply equations for groundnuts and cotton were all estimated by ordinary least squares. It became obvious at an early stage that there was auto- correlation in our series. Whether this is a serious drawback depends on the purposes to which we intend to put our estimates. For prediction purposes Malinvaud maintains that though the estimates of the coefficients may be imprecise, predictions based on them "are nevertheless 13 fairly good." I decided to incorporate some knowledge of the autoregressive structure in my analysis for the purposes of prediction.14 I therefore ran first stage ordinary least squares for all equations. For the ground- nut equations, I assumed a first order autoregressive scheme and estimated the autocorrelation coefficient from the residuals yielded by my first stage estimates. These autocorrelation coefficient estimates were then used to transform the original variables; in the second stage, ordinary least squares was applied to the transformed variables. This transformation exercise produced inconclusive results; it was therefore not done for the cotton equations. 141 Most of the equations were of the linear and log forms. The original equation is designated by its number, like (6); the same equation reestimated with transformed variables to take account of the autoregressive structure is designated (6)'. The "short run" sales supply function for groundnuts was postulated in two forms as: Y1t = 8° + B1X2t + B2X3t + 6t (6) log Y1t = 80 + Bllogx2t + leogx3t + 6t (7) where: Ylt is the quantity (tons) of sales of groundnuts to the Northern States Marketing Board in year t; th is the net producer price of groundnuts paid by the board in year t (LN/ton) and X3t, standing for the real income of consumers of groundnuts, is GDP at factor cost (LN), and where the disturbance terms (at) are assumed to obey normal classical linear regression assumptions. The estimated equations and their transformed counterparts for the Northern States (1950-51 through 1967-68), with standard errors of estimates in brackets,are: ?lt = -440875.6 + 12729.7x2t + 588.6X3t, R2 = .83 (224368.5) (6267.2) (69.3) d = 2.25 6 = -0.1448 (6) §lt = -354514.3 + 9224.9xzt + 577.2x3t, R2 = .86 (524678.5) (11945.3) (79.1) d = 2.17 (6)' 142 2 log vlt = .6013 + 1.3139 iogx2t + 1.0492 109X3t, R = .86 (.6023) (.3379) (.1255) d = 2.03 8 = -o.0230 (7) log ilt = 2.0636 + .5901 1ogx2t + .9305 logx3t, R2 = .74 (1.4566) (.7323) (.1625) d = .2.22 (7)' In equation (6) the sign of the groundnut price coefficient is consistent with theory; it is significantly positive at the 5 per cent level. The elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the marketing board with respect to the board's net producer price is .714, calculated at the sample means. The real income coefficient is positive and significant at the .5 per cent level. The sign could be due to two reasons: an implication that groundnuts in 15 so that the form sold to the board are an inferior good with rising incomes less is consumed in the domestic market and more is sold to the board, or it could be due to the effect of the measure of income we used on the ability of farmers, producers, and middlemen to produce and sell more groundnuts to the board as incomes rise, especially in a world of imperfect capital markets. The fit of the model is quite good (R2 = .83); the calculated partial correlation coefficient between groundnuts sales and groundnut prices is .464 while the partial correlation coefficient between groundnut sales and income is .909. The null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation was not rejected at the 5 per cent level (the Dubin-Watson Statistic, d, = 2.25). Equation (6)' is the transformed 143 counterpart of (6): the autocorrelation coefficient is calculated as -0.l4475 from the residuals of (6); this is then used to transform the variables in (6) after which ordinary least squares (OLS) is used to estimate the 16 Though (6)' improves the overall transformed equation. fit of the model (R2 = .86) and reduces the autocorrelation, the statistical significance of the groundnut price coefficient is drastically reduced. In equation (7), the groundnut price coefficient has the expected sign and it is statistically significant at the .5 per cent level. A two tailed t-test finds the coefficient statistically significant at the l per cent level. From (7), the elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the marketing board with respect to the board's net producer price is 1.3139, meaning that if the board raises groundnut producer prices by l per cent, groundnut sales to the board will increase by 1.3139 per cent. The income coefficient is positive and is statistically significant at the .5 per cent level. The fit of the model is quite good: R2 = .86; the partial correlation coefficient between groundnut sales and its net producer price is .708, the partial correlation coefficient between groundnut sales and income is .907 and the Dubin-Watson statistic is 2.03. "R2 deletes" for equation (7) show that 72 per cent of the variation in sales of groundnuts is explained by the model if we regress sales only on income and 21 per cent is explained if we regress sales only on net producer 144 price. The transformation of (7) with the estimated autocorrelation coefficient (8 = -0.0230) did not improve my results: the price coefficient fell drastically in statistical significance (significantly positive only at the 25 per cent level); the income coefficient, though statistically significant at the .5 per cent level, fell; R2 fell to .74 and the Dubin—Watson statistic rose to 2.22. From (4) above, total stocks of groundnuts in a given marketing period should be one of our regressors. We have no data or reliable estimates of total output of groundnuts. It can be presummed that the marketing board in deciding on the net producer price it pays to farmers in any given year is to some extent influenced by the expected output of the crop for that year. Thus, antici- pation of a small crop would induce the board to pay producers higher net producer prices in that year and conversely for anticipations of large crOps. It is plausible then to expect some negative correlation between the output series and the net producer price series. To this extent, the ommission of output from our short run equations may underestimate the price elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the board. We would expect the elasticity of sales to the board with respect to stock output to be positive. To capture some long run influences on groundnut sales to the board, the prices of competitive crops were 145. included in some regression equations. X5 is the guinea corn price relative to the groundnut price, and X6 is the millet price relative to the groundnut price. If millets and guinea corn are each competitive with groundnuts in production, we would expect the elasticity of ground- nut sales to the board with respect to X5 and X to be 6 negative. The Institute of Agricultural Research, Samaru, Zaria has been breeding and recommending new varieties and practices for groundnut farmers over the last twenty years. If groundnut farmers have been applying fertilizers, seed dressing and spraying, new varieties and new cultural practices, then there should have been a secular trend in yields per acre which in turn should have given an upward trend to groundnut sales to the marketing board. This would render the coefficient of the trend variable, X4, positive. On the other hand, transportation facilities have steadily improved over the years, thus facilitating the shipment of groundnuts from surplus to deficit areas. This might render the trend coefficient negative in sign. The estimated equations, with standard errors of coefficients in brackets, are: 91t = 783789.1 + 12813.3x2t + 1003.8x3t - 27866X4t, R2 = .85 (997276.3) (6148.7) (336.7) (22132.9) d = 2.26 5 = -.135 (8) 91t a 1004923.2 + 7629.4x2t + 988.3X3t - 28323.9X4t, R2 = .80 (1306147.8) (11865.8) (355.8) (22569.6) d = 2.19 (8)' 146 163 Ylt = 3.096 + .899 iogx3t + .378 logxst - .101x6t_1 (9) (.433) (.140) (.159) (.160) R2 = .81 d = 2.72 s = —o.305 log Ylt = 2.892 + .956 iogx3t + .332 iogx6t - .082 iogx6t, (9)' (.310) (.097) (.127) .125) R2 = .91 d = 2.44 The trend coefficient in (8) and (8)' is significantly negative at the 25 per cent level. The negative sign could be due to several reasons: improved transportation and market information networks that facilitate diversion of the crop from producing areas to other domestic markets; a probable upward trend in the demand for indigenously crushed groundnut oil, or exogenous increases in popu- lation.17 Relative to equation (7), the income coefficient has increased substantially while the price coefficient remains remarkably stable; both are statistically signifi- cant at the 5 per cent level. The overall fit of the model is good: R2 = .86; the calculated partial corre- lation coefficients between groundnut sales and the leX2 leX3 = .623 and deletes" indicate that when individual variables are: 2 = .486; pY1X4 = -.318. The R groundnut sales are regressed only on income and time, 80 per cent of the variation in groundnut sales is 147 explained; when sales are regressed only on groundnut prices and time, 75 per cent of the variation in groundnut sales is explained and when sales are regressed only on groundnut prices and income, 83 per cent of the variation in groundnut sales is explained. Transformation of (8) into (8)' using the calculated autocorrelation coefficient from the residuals of (8) did not improve the results: the statistical significance of the price coefficient is drastically reduced and R2 falls. The income coefficient is fairly stable, falling from 1003.8 to 988.3 but still statistically significant at the 5 per cent level. Regressing groundnut sales on last year's groundnut price yielded poor results. Regressing sales on last year's groundnut price and this year's income improved the overall fit of the model: A log ylt = 7.8426 + 1.5342 log x2t-1; R2 = .37 (1.7226) (.4994) d = 1.20 (10) A log Ylt = 3.9516 + 1.1084 logX3t + .4500 log X2t-13 R2 = .76 (1.3556) (.2249) .3873) d = 2.43 (11) The coefficient of the log of groundnuts price is significantly positive at the 0.5 per cent level in (10); this is reduced to 25 per cent in (11). The coefficient of the log of income is significantly positive at the 0.5 per cent level. The reduction in the elasticity of groundnut sales with respect to last year's price when income is included as one of the regressors suggests 148 positive correlation between income and lagged groundnut price.18 To check for irreversibilities in the sales supply curve, we postulated a model of the form Ylt = 8° + 82X2t—1 + B3X3t + B4(X2t—1 ° th) + 8t where: zlt = 1 1f x2t-1 i x2t-2 = 0 otherwise; the other variables are defined as before. If irreversibilities in the underlying investment- disinvestment process are significant enough to transmit their influence to the groundnut sales supply curve, then 84 is not zero. Alternatively, the model could be stated as = I Y1t Bo + (82 + B4)X2t-l + 83X3t + s (when the board s groundnut net producer prices are not rising); = u ylt 80 + BZXZt-l + B3X3t + 8 (when the board 3 groundnut net producer prices are rising). A test of whether the elasticity of groundnut sales to the board with respect to the board's net producer price differs according to whether prices are rising or falling 19 is a test of the hypothesis that 84 = O. The estimated equation is: 149 91t = -133373.9 + 3295.4x2t_1 + 597.7x3t - 1565.1(X2t_1 - 2t) (186118.1) (6232.2) (101.7) (1940.6) R2 = .76 d = 2.04 (12) In (12), the lagged price coefficient is of the right sign but is not significant at the 25 per cent level; the income coefficient is significantly positive at the .5 per cent level; the coefficient of the interaction effect between the dummy variable and the lagged groundnut price is significantly negative at the 25 per cent level, significantly non-zero at the 50 per cent level for a two- tailed test. The fit of the model is good: R2 = .76 and the Dubin Watson statistic is around 2. Thus, the influence of these irreversibilities is not particularly strong on the sales supply curve. They are likely to be important if we focused solely on supply (output) considerations; our model admits these long run influences through the side door, as it were. A model focusing solely on output (supply) response to producer price might produce differ- ent results. A non-significant difference between expansion sales supply price elasticities and contraction sales supply price elasticities does not necessarily imply that there are no irreversibilities in the underlying investment and disinvestment response to groundnuts price changes. The most recent history of the board's groundnut producer 20 prices, the factors influencing the way Northern States 150 farmers form and revise their expectations of the board's prices are all factors that influence the investment- disinvestment decisions of farmers and thus influence groundnut sales to the board. For sales of cotton to the marketing board, the following equation was estimated by ordinary least squares. log Y2t = 80 + 81 log X2t + 82109 X3t + Et where Y2t is the sales of cotton (tons) to the Northern States Marketing Board in year t, X is the net producer 2t price of cotton (LN/ton) based on the price series that I have constructed (see p. 109), X is the income variable 3t (LN) meant to capture the same effects as in the case of groundnuts: in this case, it is the effect of income on the demand for indigenously woven material and probably the effect of the producer income effect on sales of cotton to the board. The estimated equation for the period 1950/51-1967/68 is: A log Y2t = .6768 + .9028 log X + .9212 log X : 2 2t 3t R .73 (.4204) (.1454) d 2.55 (13) The price coefficient is of the right sign; it is signifi- cantly positive at the 2.5 per cent level. Since (13) depicts mainly short run influences, the "short run" elasticity of sales of cotton to the marketing board with respect to the board's net producer price is .9028, 151 meaning that an increase in the board's net producer price of l per cent would lead to an increase in sales of cotton to the board of almost 1 per cent, all other vari- ables remaining constant. The positive sign of the income coefficient may reflect the fact that as incomes have risen, the demand for most indigenous weaving (except for specialty fabrics like Okene cloth) has declined and thus has led to an increase in cotton sales to the board or it may capture the effect of generally rising incomes on the ability of cotton farmers, producers, and middlemen to produce and sell cotton to the board, especially in a world of imperfect capital markets. The fit of the model is good: R2 = .73, the calculated partial correlation coefficient between cotton sales and its producer price is .48 while the partial correlation coefficient between cotton sales and income is .85. Based on our results from the groundnut equations, we found no compelling reason to reestimate (13) with the calculated autocorrelation coefficient from the residuals of (13). Our sales price elasticity of cotton exceeds Oni's price elasticity of supply of cotton (output) as would be expected since output supply as such is more likely to be affected by certain irreversibilities in the underlying investment- disinvestment process.21 To capture some long run influences on cotton sales to the board, we regressed cotton sales on lagged 152 producer price of cotton (XZt-l) and income. We obtained poor results. The estimated equation (1951-67), with standard errors of estimates in brackets, was: 2 — 2.4398 + .1714 log X2t-l + .7492 log x3t, R (.4859) (.1795) d log Y .56 2t 2.54 (14) The lagged price coefficient is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the income coefficient is significantly positive at the 0.5 per cent level. The null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation was rejected at the 5 per cent level. To capture the substitution effects in production, we introduced the lagged price of groundnuts relative to the lagged price of cotton (§%E3%), the lagged price of millets relative to the lagged cotton price (:::::) and the lagged price of guinea corn relative to the lagged cotton price (:::::). To the extent that a crop is competitive with cotton in production, we expect the elasticity of sales of cotton to the board with respect to this crop's (lagged) price relative to cotton's (lagged) price to be negative. The estimated equations for the period 1951-67, with standard errors of estimates in brackets, were: x log‘Y2t = 1.04828 + .2088 log XZt-l - 2.0905 log ( 41:“1) + (.4401) (1.0324) 2t-l 1.0687 log x3t; R2 = .67 (.2264) d = 2.97 (15) 153 X 1og"):2t = 2.2157 + .0992 log x2t__1 - .4059 log (XSt J‘) + .8196 log x3t; (1.1764) (.2359) 211-1 (.3870) R2 = .51 d =3 3.16 (16) A X6t-1 log Y2t = 2.4222 + .0975 109 X2t-1 - .3109 109 (X ) + .7589 log X312; R2 = .48 d = 3.18 (17) In (15) the lagged own price coefficient (XZt-l) is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the price of groundnuts relative to cotton is of the right sign and is significant at the 5 per cent level while the income coefficient is significantly 22 The overall fit of positive at the 0.5 per cent level. the model is fair (R2 = .67). In (16) the own lagged price coefficient is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the lagged millet price relative to lagged cotton price is of the right sign and is significantly negative at the 10 per cent level while the income coefficient is signifi- cant at the l per cent level. In (17), the own lagged price is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the lagged guinea corn price relative to lagged cotton price is of the right sign and is signifi- cant at the 10 per cent level; the income coefficient is significant at the 10 per cent level. Both (16) and (17) are fair in overall fit; in both, the null hypothesis of 154 zero autocorrelation was rejected at the 5 per cent level. There appears to have been competition in production between cotton, groundnuts, millet, and guinea corn. Our attempt to include a trend variable (X7) in equation (14) changed the sign of lagged cotton price. The estimated equation was:23 log Y = .3772 - .1602 log X 2t + 2.8052 log X - .0603 X (.4046) Zt’l (.7058) 3t (.0202)7t d = 2.80 (18) The lagged cotton price has the wrong sign; the trend variable is negative and is significant at l per cent. The negative sign may reflect structural changes in the transportation and market information networks over time, thus facilitating the shipment of cotton from surplus to deficit areas particularly for the specialty woven fabrics. To test for the effects of certain irreversibilities of the underlying investment-disinvestment process on sales of cotton to the board, we postulated a model of the forms: log Y2t = Bo + 81 log X + 82 log X3t + 83 (Z t log X ) + 8 2t-1 1 2t-1 t 0< II 80 + 81 log x + B x3t + 83 (x - s ) + 8 2t 2t-1 2 2t-1 1t t 155 where: B = 1 if X 1t X 2t-1 i 2t-2 0 otherwise; the other variables are defined as before. If irreversibilities in the underlying investment- disinvestment process are significant enough to transmit their influence to the cotton sales supply curve, then 83 is not zero.24 Alternatively, the model could be stated as log Y 2t = Bo + (81 + 83) log X + 82 log X + at (when the 2t-1 3t board's cotton net producer prices are not rising); log Y = 80 + 81 log X + 82 log X + 6 (when the board's cotton 2t 2t-1 3t t net producer prices are rising); and +E3) 1 3 x2t-1 + B th = so + (B (when the board's cotton net 2X3t producer prices are not rising); Y2 + B + B X (when the board's cotton net producer t = 8o 1 X2t-1 2 3t prices are rising). A test of whether the elasticity of cotton sales to the board with respect to the board's net producer differs according to whether prices are rising or not is a test of the hypothesis that 83 = 0. The estimated 156 equations, with standard errors of estimates in brackets, were: 106 Y2t = 2.5885 + .0855 log x2t_1 + .7544 log x3t - .0167 (.5274) (.1847) (.0328) (Z logX ) 82 = 57 1t 2t'1 d = 2.50 (19) ? = 7262.4 + 445.7 x + 72.1 x - 175.1 (x - z ) 2t (1131.4?t l (19.1)3t (247.1) 2t 1 1t R2 = .54 d = 2.59 (20) In (19), the coefficient of the lagged cotton price is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the income coefficient is significantly positive at the 0.5 per cent level, while the coefficient of the inter— action term between the dummy variable and the lagged cotton price is not significant at the 25 per cent level. In (20) the coefficient of the lagged cotton price is of the right sign but is insignificant at the 25 per cent level; the income coefficient is significantly positive at the 0.5 per cent level while the coefficient of the interaction term between the dummy variable and the lagged cotton price is significantly negative at the 25 per cent level. The fit of both models is fair; the null hypothesis of zero autocorrelation was rejected at the 5 per cent level. Though our results do not indicate any particularly strong influence of irreversibilities on the sales supply curve, two things must be noted: first, our test is weak 157 insofar as it fails to take into account the influence of magnitudes of price changes on the investment-disinvestment decisions of farmers and second, we are not directly focusing on output (supply) and all its relevant long run considerations. The following conclusions can be drawn. In all the equations for both groundnuts and cotton, sales to the marketing board are very price responsive on the average; both the price coefficient and the income coefficient are stable with respect to exclusion and inclusion of several other variables. We tried to cope with the autoregression problem in the following way. We estimated the groundnut equations in the original variables and calculated the autocorrelation coefficient from the residuals of our first stage OLS estimates. The calculated autocorrelation coefficient was then used to transform the original vari- ables after which OLS was used to estimate the transformed equation. The results of this exercise are mixed: in some cases, the overall fit of the model improved and autocorrelation was reduced; in others, things got worse.25 That is why no transformation was performed for the cotton equations. Our efforts to detect irreversibilities in the underling investment-disinvestment relations produced rather inconclusive results. This was probably partly due to our rudimentary knowledge of the factors influencing farmers individually and in the aggregate with regards 158 to their formation and revision of expectations about the board's net producer prices and partly because we were not mainly concerned with the long run factors. The multicolinearity problem was not as serious as might be expected; for example, the simple correlation was-0.165. coefficient between X and X 6t 6t-1 Prediction Our efforts at correcting for the autoregressive structure yielded mixed results. We, therefore, predict sales of groundnuts to the board using both the original estimated regression equations as well as some reestimated regression equations that do incorporate knowledge of the autoregressive structure and predict sales of cotton using the untransformed estimated equations. For the 1948-67 period, groundnut net producer prices paid by the board had a mean percentage of world 26 Three differ- groundnut market prices of 55.01 per cent. ent series of annual groundnut net producer prices were then constructed on the assumption that the board paid groundnut farmers the following percentages of world market groundnut prices for each of the years 1950-1967; 55 per cent, 60 per cent, and 67.8 per cent. We stay on one side of the actual mean percentage that obtained during the period 1948-67 (= 55 per cent) because we want to investigate the sales and government and marketing board revenue consequences of paying farmers higher 159 producer prices. It is assumed that the other variables in the estimated equations used for predicing sales stay at their initial values: there is only a new value for groundnut price for each of the years 1950-67. The results are shown in Tables 5.1, 5.2, 5.3, and 5.4, with the standard errors of predictions in brackets. It is evident from these tables that in terms of receiving a percentage of world prices, Northern States groundnut farmers did much better in the 1960's than in the 1950's: in the 1950's, they received less than 55 per cent of world prices while in the 1960's they received more than 55 per cent of world prices. Thus, predicted sales, assuming farmers received 55 per cent of world prices, tend to be higher than actual sales to the board in the 1950's and lower than actual sales to the board in the 1960's. This same trend is exhibited even if we suppose that farmers were paid 60 per cent of world prices as shown in Tables 5.3 and 5.4. To avoid cases in which our new hypothetical prices are lower than the actual prices farmers received, we suppose the board paid farmers a price: Pth = max(Pth, .6 Pwt) where Pth is the board's actual price that was paid to farmers in year t and Pwt is the world price of groundnuts 27 in year t. The constructed price series and the resulting predicted sales are shown in Table 5.5. 160 .HHH .m mom .moamm was museum uwooooum assess mom "condom momeom AaommHHVmOhbbo Hoemhm m.mm o.om noma mmammm Ahmemaavmammom snowmoa m.mm o.mm mama Homhmb Amvmmoavmmamam ommwnm m.nm ~.vm moma censor Amwamoavommohb hmhmhw m.mm H.vm voma ommmmo Aboamoavmmmmmm hmhmmb m.vm >.~m moma memoam Avoemoavmmammo vumabm m.mm m.om mood maammm Ammmmoavmmbvmm mvmmmm H.vm m.om Hood oemamm Amvamoavaeamvm Hmomao m.mm >.mm coma Hoavom Ameomoavmohmmm Heemvv o.Hm v.bm mmma mommmm Ammmomavammamo ommmmm m.me v.0m mmma ovomvm Aaoomaavmmaaao mmovah m.o¢ m.mm omma mwwmmv Amhmooavvvoamv mmmhmm o.mm ¢.bm mmma emomam Ammohaavo>hmmm mHNOmm N.~v ¢.mm mmma mmommv Ammmoaavhamaam mhhmmhm H.mm v.mm vmma bbmmav Annemaavmaomme mvmvmv m.~v m.mm mmma mbmame AmmmeHVvamom movemv h.mv o.mm mmma vmmmhm Aoamvmavmmmnvv mmmmmv m.me 0.0m Hmma mommae Aavmmmavmemaam MthvH m.am N.H~ omma mace coa\zm Amusuosuuw Amusuosuum oueom moaum ousom use» e>nmnonmouous< m>wmmmumouous< on» tauos no any hp mo moccasocu mo emoeazocx on meaem ucmo mom mm name mcaueuomuooch mcwosHuxmv amouo< owed ousom moowmm .Amv cowumswm “my cowuesvm we mooamm umuuooum advanced Hmsuod so venom moamm omuoaomum .nnoauonoa .mauoonz .mmumun cumsuuoz .Ho>oa pauoz «0 ammo mom mm as manned pumom mcwuoxumz mcwssmmd mmamm usaocsouw couoapoumll.a.m mqmda .a.m manna ca coaumswm Hoocaa on» coma Hmsoa maasumcem one scaumsvm man» spas meaMm oeuoaomum .wnmc camuno omas a.m wanes Ca we mwamm owuoaoeum one meoaum omnammnuommn ca ocmuu 056m one ”0902 .aaa .m mom .meamm was mooaum monotone assuom mom "meadow 161 momomo bmmoam aovmmm m.mm o.m~ hmma mommmm womovh havomoa m.m~ o.m~ moma amaomm momemo ommmmm m.m~ ~.vm moma manoma mnoaen noose m.m~ a.vm onoa mmoomm maammm smoomm o.v~ m.mm moma mmmmmm mommmv vmmamm m.m~ m.om moma moomme mmmmme mommmm a.vm m.om aoma mmmmem mmmmmv amomam w.mm m.mm omma mmoovm mmevam aevmev n.am «.mm mmma mmmmmm mmmmmm emmmmm m.mv v.0m mmma ommmmm memmmm mmovam m.ov m.mm mmma mmmmmv mmvmhv Nmmbmm o.mm v.mm mmma mmmovm mmmmmo mamomm «.mv v.mm mmma Nwmomv mommmm common a.mm «.mm vmma mmoovv ommoom mememv m.~v m.mm mmma mmmvmv mmmoam mmoomv m.me o.mm mmma enmemm emamve mmmmmv m.mv 0.0m amma mmnamm hmmmmv memmva m.am ~.am omma mcoe coa\zm amusuosuum ammsuosnum oumom moans oumom use» e>ammeum0uous¢ m>ammommmuousm emu ou oauoz mo ecu an no emoeasocx mo emcoazocx mmamm ucmo mom mm camm mcaumuomuoocav mcaosaoxmv assuom came oumom mooamm .amv coaumswm any scaumsom ma meoaum monotone Monotone assuom so venom mmamm touoanwum .noxenoauan\onoa .maumoaz .mouoon cumcuuoz .am>ea panos mo ucmu new mm um meoaum ousom mcassmmd mmamm usaocsouw emuoapwumll.~.m mamda 162 .ue30a maamuecem ens eusuosmum e>ammeumenousm ecu mo emoeasocx mcaumuomuouca meaMm oeuoaoeum .Aomma udeuxev meuaum oauos mo uceo uem oo cmcu mmea oe>aeoeu mnesumm cec3 m.omma ecu ou ummuucou ca .meoamd oauoz mo uceo nee oo oeuMasumom ecu cmcu uecmac ones meoaum neocooum amouom .ooma now umeoxe m.ooma ecu CH .~.m use a.m meacme ca cmcu meoaum Hecmac cuas necmac ens meamm oeuoaoeum .aaa .m eem .measm use meoaum meosooum amsuom mom aamommavmmmemo amaomaavmmmmom aovmho a.o~ o.o~ moma avooaeavvvmmmm mammaaavooommm mmeomoa m.om o.mm ooma ammmmaavmmmoam amvmmoavooonvm ommmmm m.mm ~.vm moma aaoomaavmeoaom ammamoavammom ommono m.om a.vm voma aommmmavewamom aooaooavhvmomm ommomm m.om >.~m moma ammmoeavvmvmmo avovooavmaoamo vmmamm o.m~ m.om aoma aemmovavmammom ammmmoavmoommm mvmmmo m.om m.om aoma onmmmavvmommm amvamoavomommm amomao «.mm m.mm ooma aoommoavmm>0mm amvoooavomvoom avvmvv m.vm «.mm mmma commaoavmooomo amomevavmomvmh vmmmmm o.mv v.om mmma avvmamavomommm avmmmmavamammo mmovam m.vv m.mm mmma Ammvaaavveaomv commooavmmmmmm Nmmmmm o.om v.hm omma ammemavooamvm aammomavmmommo m.m0mm a.ov v.~m mmma aaavmaavammmmv avmmmaavooammm ohmmbm o.me ¢.mm vmma aobvmmavmmommv Ammmmmavmmommm meoome N.oe m.mm mmma ammmvoavammoov amaomvavmmmmmm omoomv m.mv o.mm mmma covavvavavmmav ammvmmavmaawmv mommmo m.mv o.om amma amoaommvboommv awmmmmavaaooom mommva w.mm n.am omma mcoa coa\zm censuosuum censuosuuw ousom eoaum venom noes e>ammeumeuousc e>ammeumeuous¢ ecu ou cauoz mo ecu mc mo emoeasocx mo emoeasocx meaem uceu Hem oo oamm mcaumuomuoocav mcaosaoxmv aesuoc oamm oueom meoaum .aov GOaumsvm aov c0aumsvm ma meoaum neosooum neusooum amsuoc co oemem meamm oeuoaoeum .ao cOausDwm co cememv wo\homalam\omma .sauemaz .meumum cuecuuoz .ae>ea oauoz mo uceu Hem oo um meoaum oueom mcaESmmc meamm unconsono Ueuuaoeumll.m.m mamce .163 .m.m manna. ca scaumsoe umecaa ecu cmcu nesoa maamuecem ems scaussoe macu cuas meawm oeuoaoeum "euoz .aaa .m eem .meaem one meoanm neocooum aesuom Mom ”eousom mammoo hmommm aovmmo a.om o.o~ moma momovm momomm mueomoa m.0m o.mm ooma emoomo whomon ommmmm m.mm ~.vm moma maamob hommmm mmooho m.om a.vm voma ommvmo oommoo baboon m.o~ b.mm moma mmmmao mmmmam ommaom o.mm m.om moma mmomnm aOOMmo memmmo m.om n.0m aoma ovoanm mommom amomao «.mm h.mm ooma memmom mmmomm aovmvo m.em e.mm mmma mmmooo amomom vmmmmm o.me v.om mmma ommvao vmommm mmovam m.vv m.mm omma vemamm mmmmmm mmmbmm o.om «.mm omma mvmmmm omoeo> manomm a.ov «.mm mmma emboam ommmmm ommmmm o.~v v.mm emma ammomv momaom ovoomv m.ov m.mm mmma mmvmmv mmvmmm omo0mv m.mv o.mm mmma ommmav ooommv mmmmmv m.>v o.om amma aovuav mvomvm mommva m.mm n.am omma woos coa\zm censuosuum censuosuum oumom eoaum oumom nee» e>ammeumeuousc e>ammenmeuousc ecu ou oauoz mo ecu an no emoeasocx mo emoeasocx meamm uceu Hem oo came mcausnomnoocav mcaosaoxmv assuuc cane oumom meoaum .amv coaumsom any coaumsvm ma meoaum ueosooum neocooum amsuoc co oemmm meamm oeuuaoeum ..n coaumsom co commas mo\oooauan\onma .mauomaz .moumun cuecuuoz .ae>ea cauoz mo uceu uem oo um meoaum Unmom mcaesmmc meaMm useocsouu oeuoaoeumll.v.m mamce .uesoa ewe ensuosuum e>ammeumeuousm ecu mo emoeasocx mcaumu nomnouca macauoaoeum .meoaum oases mo uceo new oo ens use» zone ca meuaum cec3 emocu cscu .emmue>o ecu co .uecmac euooeuecu eum euec meamm oeuoaoeum eca .oe>aeoeu ec meoaum amsuom ecu ou aesve no cecu ueuweum one meoaum mm moo emuos uoc ueEMMM ecu mebmea moaoaum amoauecuommc ece "euoz .aaa .m eem .meamm use meoaum neosooum aesuos Mom ”eousom 164 mmmemo mmmmOb aovmmo a.om o.om boma evmmmm oovmmm hmvomoa m.om o.mm ooma Nmaomw ooaaom ommmmm N.vm N.om moma omaaom mmmomm mmmomo a.em a.vm voma mommmm mammmm mmhomh m.mm m.~m moma ommvmo oaombo emmamm n.0m n.0m moma mmooao mmmmvo mvmmmo m.om m.om aoma momvoo aommvo amomao m.mm >.mm ooma ammmmm mmmmao avvmvv v.mm v.om mmma Nooomo momeo vmmmmm o.mo ¢.om mmma omommm aoammo mmoeam m.ve m.nm mmma emOmmv omonvm ammomm v.mm v.hm omma ooamvm «mommo mam0mm a.oe v.mm mmma ammmmv moahmm omhmmm o.~e v.mm vmma mmommv mmommm ovovmv ~.oo m.mm mmma ammooe moommm omoOmv m.mv o.mm mmma avmmav maammv mmmmmv m.hv o.om amma moommo aaooom mvmmva m.mm n.am omma mcoe coa\zu 3 . eflz censuosuum censuusuum oueom a mo nmv oumom umew e>ammeumeuousc e>ammeumemou54 ecu ou xms u .wm ecu mu mo emoeasocx mo emoea3ocx meamm came ounom ease mcaueuomuoocav mcaosaoxmv amsuoc ma meuaum meoaum .aov scaumsmm cod scaumsvm ueusooum ueosooum aesuoc so oemmm measm oeuoaoeum .mo\homauam\mmma .eauemaz .meumum cuecuuoz .eoaum pauoz ecu ma 3m use eoaum ueosooum aesuoc ecu ma .zm euecs asmo. .anv xmsnnam us eoaum oueom mcassmmc meamm unconsouo oeuuaceumlu.m.m mamce 165 A pricing policy of paying farmers 55 per cent of world prices would have benefitted farmers most of the 1950's but would have hurt them most of the 1960's. This fact is also reflected in the predicted sales relative to actual sales. Preference for this policy over the actual one that was followed could be justified thus: first, if there are any substantial irreversibilities in the under- lying investment-disinvestment relations in groundnut production, then paying farmers higher net producer prices in the 1950's would have expanded productive capacity with the result that in the presence of taxes in the 1960's there would have been much more over production relative to the present state of affairs as there would have been no tendency towards investment or disinvestment in these resources because of these irreversibilities; second, for long run allocative purposes marketing board prices that are linear functions of world prices that should ultimately guide farmers' production decisions are preferrable to prices that either have no functional relationship to world prices (as when election year politics and the political party in power determine board prices) or prices that may be nonlinear functions of world prices. These comments are applicable to subsequent tables. Tables 5.6 and 5.7 show the effects of hypothesized new groundnut prices on government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts. Over the period, there are more .lf56 TABLE 5.6.--Tax Revenue: Estimated Changes From Higher Groundnut Prices, Larger Vblume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, l950-l965.‘ a Change Fromb Change From Higher Prices Net Change in Year Higher Prices and Larger Volume Tax Revenue: (PNj pNj)Mj (Pp -P Nj)(Mj- Mj) a + b EN 1950 -4,938,907.8 513,44l.6 -4,425,466.2 1951 -4,809,144.4 43,518.0 -4,765,626.4 1952 -6,4l7,370.4 50,033.2 -6,367,337.2 1953 -4,543,733.6 1,009,028.6 -3,534,705.0 1954 -2,683,987.2 l,695,845.2 -988,142.0 1955 -7,263,945.5 -49l,697.5 -7,755,643.l 1956 501,104.8 859,505.0 l.360,609.8 1957 -7,432,859.2 -503,090.3 -7,935,949.5 1958 -7,040,272.8 -3,501,07l.4 -10,933,930.6 1959 l,29l,778.9 615,629.5 l,907.408.4 1960 3,404,780.5 -7l3,3l3.0 3,691,467.5 1961 2,742,196.0 -l,133,160.4 l,609,035.6 1962 4,619,077.2 -213,215.7 4,405,861.S 1963 4,563,016.6 -574,848.0 3,988,168.6 1964 2,233,430.l 1,43l,086.4 3,664,516.5 1965 4,202,476.0 -l,759,225.5 2,443,250.S Note: For PNj , PN , Mj and M5 figures, see Table 5. 3. The potential producer price figures were obtained by jjadding the composite tax per ton on groundnuts for each year (see Table 4.3: p. 111) to P“, the actual net producer price. For derivation of the three columns, see p. 168. In the first column the change is negative (a reduction in the revenue from groundnuts) for most of the 1950's when hypothetical prices exceed actual prices: the converse holds for the 1960's: the 1950's thus correspond to a gain to farmers while the 1960's correspond to losses to them due to the new prices, relative to actual prices and actual sales. The second column corresponds to neither gains nor losses to farmers. The last column is defined as the Eg£_change in government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts as a result of the new prices. It is the second column plus the first, i.e., Pl ) (MI - - C ’ - - ’ O ’ I (pp Nj j Mj) (PNj Psi)": Mij M p ’p + M p + p Mj i p "3 Ni 3 Ni Mi 9 M’ - M + p M - M “P 9‘3 3’ N33 3N3 Now, we can derive the last column from first principles. It is the difference between total government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts using the new hypothetical prices and total government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts using the actual producer prices paid by the board, i.e., M (pp - P ) - M (p - p ) - M’p - M p’ -M p + M p P(M’ - M j u: jp u: jp in: :p 3N3' Pp: 3"“ '"P j N) 1 Ni which is exactly the same expression for the third column derived above. *For H; see Table 5.1, equation (6). 167 years in which the hypothetical prices exceed actual prices than those in which they fall below them. In Tables 5.6-5.8, the first column shows the change in government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts due to the new prices (Pfij)° The change involves a reduction in tax revenue if the new price exceeded the actual price and an increase in tax revenue if new prices were below actual prices. The second column shows the change in government and marketing board tax revenue due to the new prices when account is taken of the effect of the new prices on sales to the board. It is defined as the "tax" using the new price multiplied by the difference between the predicted sales to the board using the new prices and sales to the board under actual prices. An increase in tax revenue occurs when sales to the marketing board increase. A reduction obtains when predicted sales are less than actual sales. A positive change in one year in the second column is not the negative of the corre- sponding change in the first column because the two columns are derived differently. The third column shows the net change in government and marketing board tax revenue from groundnuts when everything is considered: actual price, (new) hypothetical price, potential producer price, actual sales, and predicted sales. With the definition given to the elements of column one, the third column is the sum of the first and second columns. 168 Advocates of the revenue role of marketing boards have implicitly or explicitly assumed that all elements of the second column are zero: that sales do not change as producer prices rise or fall, so that M3 - Mj = AMj E 0 (see Table 5.6). Our entries in this column, particularly in the 1950's when hypothetical prices exceed actual prices show that these sales effects of price changes are not definitionally zero. The significance of the entries in the second column is that they partially offset the change in tax revenue from groundnuts due to the new prices relative to the actual prices and actual sales. How big is this offset? The offset is very significant in some years. In 1954 for example, as a result of higher producer prices, farmers would have gained LN 2,683,987.2, the government and marketing board would have gained LN 1,695,845.2 from the positive price sales effect, leaving the government and marketing board a net (groundnut tax) revenue loss of 5N 988,142.0. Total tax revenue from groundnuts in the 28 thus still leaving same year was LN 5,125,384,424, government and marketing board revenue at LN 4,137,242.4. Thus, even though taxes could have been drastically cut down in this year leading to extra income for farmers of over two and a half million pounds,29 total tax revenue from groundnuts would have been little affected. Simi- larly, in 1953, as a result of the postulated higher 169 producer prices, groundnut farmers in the Northern States would have gained 5N 4,543,733.6, the government and marketing board would have gained LN 1,009,028.6 from the positive price sales effect, thus leaving the government and marketing board with a net revenue loss of LN 3,534,705.0. With total tax revenue from groundnuts of LN 4,788,395.830 in the same year, the government and the marketing board would still have been left with a handsome positive balance of well over one and a quarter million pounds from groundnuts alone. In 1952, with higher producer prices, farmers would have gained in increased income LN 6,417,370.4: the government and marketing board from the positive price sales effect would have gained 5N 50,033.2, thus leaving a net tax revenue loss of LN 6,367,337.2. But with a total tax 31 this revenue from groundnuts of LN 7,375,800 in 1952, could have still left a positive balance with the govern- ment and marketing board. In 1950 and 1951 would the government and marketing board have ended up in a net total revenue deficit. For most of the other years (see Table 5.6), the government and marketing board would have been better off in revenue terms because on the average, 60 per cent of world price was less than actual producer prices. Roughly the same trends in terms of the degree to which revenue losses are offset by the positive price sales effect can be observed in Table 5.7. 170 TABLE 5.7.--Tax Revenue: Estimated Changes From Higher Groundnut Prices, Larger Vblume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1965.** Change Fromb Change Froma Larger Vblume Net Change in Year Higher Prices and Higher Price Tax Revenue: (PNj PNjH‘Ij (Pp PNj) (M3. M3.) a + b EN 1950 -4,938,907.8 485,882.4 -4,453,025.4 1951 -4,889,l44.4 421,068.0 -4,388,076.4 1952 -6,4l7,370.4 228,995.2 -6,188,375.2 1953 -4,543,733.6 1,218,588.0 -3,325,l45.6 1954 -2,683,987.2 2,025,453.6 -658,533.6 1955 -7,263,945.5 -837,700.8 -8,101,646.3 1956 501,104.8 898,115.0 l,399,219.8 1957 -7,432,859.2 213,47S.4 -7,219,383.8 1958 -7,040,272.8 -5,894,023.8 -12,934,296.6 1959 l,29l,778.9 617,819.7 l,909,598.6 1960 3,404,780.5 -1,933,975.2 1,470,805.3 1961 2,742,196.0 -2,349,085.6 393,110.4 1962 4,619,077.2 -3,474,404.2 l,l44,673.0 1963 4,563,016.6 -l,760,256.0‘ 2,802,760.6 1964 2:233o430.l 822,744.0 3:056:174-1 1965 4,202,476.0 -2,824,767.0 l,377,709.0 Source: For Pfij, Per Mj, and PP' see Table 5.4. For derivation of columns, see p. 168, and note to Table 5.6. **For MT see Table 5.4, equation (7). 3 171 With the price series PNj = max (PNj, overall extent to which lost tax revenue is offset by the 32 6Pw), the positive price sales effect is even larger. Because the new hypothetical prices never fall below actual producer prices, farmers are not worse off. In Table 5.3, it is evident that government and marketing board are better off in the 1960's while the farmers are worse off. In Table 5.5 with a new pricing policy, the farmers are not worse off at any time. In Table 5.8 the net change in tax revenue from groundnuts due to the new hypothetical prices relative to actual producer price, potential producer price, actual sales, and predicted sales to the board is shown in the third column. The zero entries in the last seven rows of the first column reflect the fact that the new prices were the same as actual prices in those years. Relative to the price series in Tables 5.6 and 5.7, the prices underlying Table 5.8 are higher in the 1960's. Farmers therefore gained. The net losses in tax revenue as a result of these higher prices in the 1960's are insignificant (third column): LN 104,553.2 in 1963. With this new pricing policy, government and marketing board policy would not have been substantially affected, on the average. Farmers would have gained without the government and marketing board being significantly worse off in revenue terms. TABLE 5.8.--Tax Revenue From Groundnuts: Higher Prices, Larger Volume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1965. 172 Estimated Changes From Change Froma Change Fromb Larger Volume Net Change in Year Higher Prices and Higher Price Tax Revenue: -(PNj-PNj)Mj (Pp-PNj .)j(M -Mj ) a + b EN 1950 —4,938,907.8 513,441.6 -4,425,466.2 1951 -4,809,144.4 43,518.0 -4,765,626.4 1952 -6,4l7,370.4 50,033.2 -6,376,337.2 1953 -4,543,733.6 1,009,028.6 -3,534,705.0 1954 -2,683,987.2 l,695,845.2 -988,l42.0 1955 -7,263,945.5 -49l,697.6 -7,755,643.l 1956 . . 682,984.8 682,984.8 1957 -7,432,859.2 -503,090.3 -7,935,949.5 1958 -7,040,272.8 -3,501,071.4 -10,933,930.6 1959 . . 302,214.6 302,214.6 1960 . . 352,835.0 352,835.0 1961 . . -346,220.4 -346,220.4 1962 . . -844,395.2 -844,395.2 1963 . . -104,553.2 -104,553.2 1964 . l,305,000.0 l,305,000.0 1965 . . 701,224.0 701,224.0 Source: For P’, , Mj see Table 5. 5. For P see P. 168 For derivation of columns sea P. 3111. Tablep5.5, equation (6). For M. J 173 In the case of cotton, only a brief description is given as the procedures for assessing government and marketing board (tax) revenue effects of changes in the board's net producer prices of cotton are the same as those used for groundnuts above. Actual producer prices paid to Northern States cotton farmers (1950-67) had a mean percentage of potential producer price (world cotton price minus all marketing costs) of 84.6 per cent.33 Three new hypothetical price series were then constructed on the assumption that the board paid cotton farmers the following percentages of world prices minus all marketing costs (i.e., potential producer price)34 in each year 1950-67: 80 per cent, 85 per cent, and 90 per cent. As with groundnuts, we stay on one side of the actual mean percentage since our primary interest is in the sales and tax revenue consequences of paying cotton farmers higher prices. However, the linear regression model is capable of handling the case of paying cotton farmers lower prices too. This new set of prices is then used to predict cotton sales, assuming other variables remain at their sample values. The results are shown in Table 5.9. From Table 5.9, our estimates indicate that if farmers were paid 85 per cent of potential producer price in each year, they could have been better off in the 1950's but worse off in the 1960's, relative to the actual 174 TABLE 5.9.--Predicted Cotton Sales Assuming Marketing Board Prices at 85 Per Cent of Potential Level, Northern States, Nigeria, 1950/51-1967/68. Predicted Actual Sales Producer Price if Board Paid Actual Producer 85 Per Cent of Sales to Using New Year Prices Potential Price the Board Prices hN/Ton Tons 1950 36.37 47.48 42,240 48,550 1951 55.07 71.90 63,679 78,341 1952 55.07 71.90 50,825 83,526 1953 54.81 83.34 75,366 102,639 1954 55.10 67.49 98,663 97,596 1955 54.68 69.47 80,791 106,514 1956 55.13 61.42 72,951 99,869 1957 54.88 58.60 123,906 99,704 1958 54.91 46.67 87,374 82,357 1959 55.07 44.58 85,892 83,569 1960 55.07 45.01 148,962 95,314 1961 46.67 39.70 83,373 89,590 1962 45.27 42.10 144,004 103,865 1963 45.27 44.43 128,585 115,729 1964 66.67 49.59 128,684 132,304 1965 46.67 46.07 127,296 130,301 1966 44.80 37.04 146,368 111,141 1967 42.93 35.50 75,519 93,272 Source: For actual prices and sales, see p. 109. For most of the 1950's, the hypothetical prices were higher than actual prices received by cotton farmers in the Northern States. Consequently, the predicted sales tend to be higher than actual sales from the positive price sales effect. The converse holds for most of the 1960's. For source of actual producer prices, see page 109. The hypothesized price series make producer prices a simple linear function of world prices and marketing costs. This is to be preferred to a situation in which producer prices are either not related to world prices (as when election year politics and the party in power determine producer prices paid by the board) or one in which producer prices are, in some (unknown) way, nonlinear functions of world prices. 175 prices they received. That is why we have constructed a new price in which we suppose the marketing board paid cotton farmers a price: P = max (P .85P th th' pt) th th is actual producer price in year t and Ppt is potential 35 producer price of cotton in year t. The predictions where P is the hypothetical new price in year t, P th The resulting changes in tax revenue from cotton based on P above are shown in Table 5.10. with the two hypothetical pricing policies are shown in Tables 5.11 and 5.12. The elements of the three columns in each table are arrived at in exactly the same way as with groundnuts. The first column shows the change in tax revenue from cotton due to the new prices, P’ relative to Nj' the actual producer price, and actual sales to the PNj , board, Mj; it is the difference between the new price and the actual price multiplied by actual sales, being negative (and thus a reduction in tax revenue) when the new price exceeds the actual price, positive (and thus an increase in tax revenue) when the new price is less than the actual price and zero when the new price equals the actual price. When the change represents a reduction in tax revenue, the entries represent a gain to farmers in monetary income; when the change represents an increase in tax revenue, farmers lose, relative to the actual prices received. 176 TABLE 5.10.--Predicted Cotton Sales Assuming Marketing Board Prices at P .-max (P ., .85P ), Northern States, Nigeria, 1950- 1967?] N3 P Producer Price Predicted if Board Paid Actual Sales Actual Producer P§.=max Sales to Using New Year Prices (PNj? .85Pp) the Board Prices bN/Ton Tons 1950 36.37 47.48 42,240 48,550 1951 55.07 71.90 63,679 78,341 1952 55.07 71.90 50,825 83,526 1953 54.81 83.34 75,366 102,639 1954 55.10 67.49 98,663 97,596 1955 54.68 69.47 80,791 106,514 1956 55.13 61.42 72,951 99,869 1957 54.88 54.60 123,906 99,704 1958 54.91 54.91 87,374 95,360 1959 55.07 55.07 85,892 101,200 1960 55.07 55.07 148,962 114,300 1961 46.67 46.67 83,373 103,800 1962 45.27 45.27 144,004 119,000 1963 45.27 45.27 128,585 117,600 1964 66.67 66.67 128,684 179,000 1965 46.67 46.67 127,296 131,800 1966 44.80 44.80 146,368 131,999 1967 42.93 42.93 75,519 110,997 period. Because farmers are never worse off in this regime as hypothetical prices are never below actual prices, predicted sales are, on the average, higher than actual cotton sales most of the . P NJ' 9 see Table 5.9. 177 TABLE 5.ll.--Tax Revenue From Cotton: Estimated Changes From Higher Prices, Larger Volume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1967. Change Fromb Change Froma Larger Volume Net Change in Year Higher Prices and Higher Price Tax Revenue: (PNj PNj)Mj (Pp PNj) (Mj Mj) a + b EN 1950 -468,864.0 159,479.9 -309,284.1 1951 -1,071,717.6 608,033.1 -463,684.4 1952 -855,384.8 414,321.7 -441,063.1 1953 -2,150,192.0 402,822.2 -1,747,369.8 1954 -l,222,434.6 -12,707.9 -1,235,142.5 1955 -1,194,898.9 314,077.8 -880,821.1 1956 -458,861.8 290,983.6 -167,878.2 1957 -460,930.3 -251,216.8 -712,l47.1 1958 719,961.8 ~41,139.4 678,822.4 1959 901,007.l -18,328.5 882,678.6 1960 1,498,557.? -432,402.9 1,066,154.8 1961 581,109.8 43,332.5 624,442.3 1962 456,492.7 -315,893.9 140,598.8 1963 103,011.4 -99,550.5 8,506.0 1964 2,197,922.7 29,973.6 2,227,896.3 1965 76,377.6 24,641.0 101,018.6 1966 1,135,815.? 227,566.4 1,363,382 1967 561,106.17 Source: For PNj' Mj and M- see Table 5.9. For derivation of columns see p. 175. 178 TABLE 5.12.--Tax Revenue From Cotton: Estimated Changes From Higher Prices, Larger volume, Individually and in Total, Nigeria, 1950-1967. Change Fromb Change Froma Larger Volume Net Change in Year Higher Prices and Higher Price Tax Revenue: (PNj PNj)Mj (Pp PNjHMj Mj) a + b EN 1950 -468,864.0 159,643.3 -309,220.7 1951 -l,071,7l7.6 608,033.1 -463,684.5 1952 855,384.8 410,900.77 -444,484.0 1953 -2,150,192.0 402,822.21 -1,?47,369.8 1954 -1,222,434.6 12,707 -1,209,727.6 1955 -1,l94,898.9 314,077.83 -880,821.1 1956 -458,861.8 290,983.58 -167.8?8.2 1957 -460,930.3 -251,216.?6 -712,147.1 1958 . . -34,649.04 —34,649.04 1959 . . -39,800.80 -39,800.80 1960 . . -159,445.20 -159,445.20 1961 . . . . . . 1962 . . -11?,518.80 -117,518.8 1963 . . -75,796.50 -75,796.5 1964 . . ~442,780.8 -442,780.8 1965 . . 34,230.40 34,230.4 1966 . . 18,679.70 18,679.? 196? . . Source: For Pfij, PNj, see p. 175. For derivation of columns see p. 176. For M3 see Table 5.10. 179 The second column shows the change in government and marketing board tax revenue from cotton due to the new hypothetical prices and new predicted sales relative to potential producer prices and actual sales. It is the difference between the potential producer price and the new price multiplied by the difference between predicted sales and actual sales. It is positive (and thus an increase in tax revenue from cotton) so long as these two differences are both positive or both negative,36 and negative (and thus a decrease in tax revenue from cotton) so long as these two differences are of opposite signs. The third column represents the BEE change in government and marketing board tax revenue from cotton due to the new prices and the predicted sales relative to actual producer prices, actual sales and potential producer price: it is the second column plus the first. Derived from first principles, it is the total tax revenue from cotton with new prices and predicted sales minus total tax revenue from cotton using actual producer prices and actual 37 Tables 5.11 and 5.12 show these results for the sales. two hypothetical price series. From Table 5.12 in 1953, with the new higher prices for farmers, farmers would have gained LN 2,150,192.0 (a loss to the government and marketing board), the government and marketing board would have gained LN 402,822.2 as a result of the positive price effect on sales, thus leaving the latter a net 180 revenue loss of LN 1,747,369.8. Total tax revenue from cotton in 1953, incorporating the price effect on sales, was calculated to be LN 4,788,395.8.38 Thus, tax revenue is not significantly affected. In 1957, as a result of the higher prices, farmers would have gained LN 460,930.3, the government and marketing board would have lost LN 251,216.76, leaving a total loss of LN 712,147.1. Total tax revenue from cotton in 1957 incorporating the positive price effect on sales would have been LN 5,857,721.9.39 The loss from paying farmers higher prices still does not substantially affect tax revenue from cotton. In 1954, with the new higher prices, farmers would have gained LN 1,222,434.6, tax revenue would have increased by LN 12,707 as a result of the positive price effect on sales thus leaving a net revenue loss to the government and the board of LN l,209,727.6. The calculated total tax revenue from cotton in same year is LN 5,125,384.4. A 20 per cent reduction in revenue with farmers gaining twice what the government and marketing board lose is certainly not a drastic reduction. For given new higher prices and marketing costs, the lower the potential producer price, the lower the gain in tax revenue resulting from the positive effect of tax increases on sales. This gain is in fact zero when potential producer price equals the new higher price as in 1961. 181 The central point is to show that the elements of the second column are not identically zero as has been implicitly assumed by those concerned about the revenue functions of the marketing boards. It is reassuring that for many years when farmers received higher producer prices, government and marketing board tax revenue from cotton was not substantially affected. Summary and Conclusions In the first part of the chapter, I presented a simultaneous equation model in which the sales supply equation of a marketing board crop was one of four structural equations of the system. Identifiability of the sales supply equation was ascertained after which the reduced form solutions of the endogenous variables were derived. The reduced form solution for sales of a crop to the marketing board could not be estimated for lack of data--avai1ability of data on the other endogenous vari- ables in the sales supply equation would have enabled us to estimate the sales supply equation by two stage least squares. The intent here was to provide a model that approximates our apriori knowledge about the variables that influence the sales of a crop to the marketing board. This simultaneous equation approach should prove useful as more data become available. The model was operationalized to remove obvious sources of biasedness and inconsistency from our ordinary flip 1’7“"‘7'737'. ;.- 182 least squares estimates. In this second section of the chapter, coefficients of regressors in the sales supply equation were estimated. For groundnuts, the sales supply equation reflecting more or less "short run" influences in linear form gave a sales supply elasticity of .714 with respect to the board's net producer price, calculated at the sample means of observations on groundnut sales and net producer prices. The log equation of groundnut sales gave an elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the board with respect to the board's producer prices of 1.3139. My efforts to correct for autocorrelation produced inconclusive results. That was why the transformation of variables with the autocorrelation coefficient calculated from the least squares residuals was done for only the groundnut equations and not done for the cotton equations. For cotton, the sales supply elasticity with respect to the board's producer price was estimated to be .90278. I tested for a difference between the expansion sales price elasticities and contraction sales price elasticities corresponding to the rising and falling phases of the marketing board's producer prices respectively. I found no significant difference. This does not necessarily mean that there are no significant irreversibilities in the investment-disinvestment relations underlying the production of groundnuts and cotton: our test was not able to capture some important relevant h -._-.a._______ Q. ' 183 factors that are known from apriori knowledge to influence farmers' investment-disinvestment decisions. In the third section of the chapter, I provided quantitative evidence on the effects on tax revenue from cotton and groundnuts of paying Northern States farmers higher prices. Predictions of sales of cotton and ! groundnuts (to the board) under different hypothetical 1 prices were made. It was found that when hypothetical , prices were higher than actual prices, predicted sales exceeded actual sales of these crops to the board. This implies that other things equal, taxes on cotton and groundnuts reduced sales of these crops to the board. These predicted sales together with the implied lower taxes on farmers were used to compute the revenue effects of (generally) higher prices to groundnut and cotton farmers in the Northern States. When the board paid farmers higher (hypothetical) prices, farmers gained in monetary income. Some of this gain however must be offset by their loss in consumer surplus as they cut down their own home consumption of these crops. We did not estimate this loss in consumer surplus. Our estimates show that the positive effect of higher prices on sales (to the board) partially offsets the loss in tax revenue due to the higher prices. Our main point has been to show that this offset of tax revenue loss is not identically zero as has been implicitly or explicitly assumed by 184 previous writers. With higher prices than the actual prices received by farmers, this tax revenue loss offset is larger, the larger the difference between predicted and actual sales. This offset is also larger the larger the difference between the potential producer price (i.e., world price minus all marketing costs) and the hypothetical price. The higher the sales price elasticity,40 the higher the predicted sales and thus the larger the offset in tax revenue loss from the positive effect of higher prices on sales to the board. The following conclusions are drawn. Sales of cotton and groundnuts to the board are very responsive to changes in the board's producer prices. The positive effect of higher (hypothetical) prices on sales to the board was able to substantially offset the crop tax revenue loss that results from paying farmers higher prices in many years in the 1950's and 1960's; in other years there would have been sizeable reduction in crOp tax revenue. There is an inevitable shortcoming in the analysis: we have not been able to account for the production effects of higher prices directly because of lack of data or even reliable estimates of total output or production of any of the crops studied. It is hoped that as more data becomes available, this factor will be incorporated in the analysis. FOOTNOTES 1We have not included smuggling in this formulation. 2Jan Kmenta, Elements of Econometrics (New York: Macmillan Co., 1971). r~***V”wsEEI ‘4‘ p. 3Ibid., pp. 543-45. 4With no compelling a riori reason to believe that either the elasticity of suppEy (output) of any marketing board crop with respect to its net producer price is unity or that the marginal propensity to consume this crop is zero, we shall, respectively, presume e and c2 to be non- zero. 0 5Charles R. Frank, Jr., Statistics and Econometrics, (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1971), p. 332. An alternative statement of the necessary and sufficient condition for identifiability is that we can form at least one nonvanishing determinant of order G-l from the coefficients with which the variables excluded from our equation appear in the G-1 other structural equations. By this criterion, 1 -a2 0 0 A* = O 0 -w2 -w 1 O O 0 with at least one largest nonsingular submatrix with rank = 3 = G-l, again showing that the sales supply equation is identified. For this alternative statement see G. Tintner, Econometrics (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc-)0 p0 13,- . 6Kmenta, op. cit., p. 551. 185 186 7For evidence which may or may not cast doubts on estimates of total output from existing data in the case of cotton, see footnote 14 on p. 125- 8This more or less corresponds to an assumption that in equilibrium, the price per unit of the crop in the domestic market equals the net producer price paid by the board net of transportation and other marketing costs. If the argument were extended to include markets in neighboring countries serviced by smugglers, then this equilibrium price also equals the net producer price in these countries properly adjusted for transportation and normal marketing costs, weighted by the probability of not getting caught (arrested) in the process of smuggling and the probability of not getting a conviction after arrest. 9This increased sale to the marketing board and reduced consumption as a result of higher marketing board prices need not be restricted to the usual substitution and income effects describing the response of consumers to price changes in their capacity as consumers per se. Indeed, in the Nigerian case, producers of most marketing board crops are consumers as well as producers of their crops. So there is a producer income effect as well as a consumer income effect. If Nigerian farmers consume a significant proportion of their crop and the (implied) income elasticity of demand for this crop is very low or negative, then an increase in the net producer price paid by the marketing board will lead to less consumption and more sales to the marketing board. 10For treatment of the dominant firm on the selling side, see G. Stigler, "Notes on the Theory of Duopoly," Journal of Political Economy (1940). 11If this were not the case, the disturbance term and the income variable would be jointly distributed which would make the OLS estimates inconsistent. 12Glenn L. Johnson, "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis," Journal of Farm Economics (1960). 13E. Malinvaud, Statistical Methods of Econometrics 2nd revised ed.; Amsterdam-London: North-Holland Publish- ing Co., 1970), p. 567. ‘m‘“ 0‘4 ..—‘-—? a s 1 ..w“' t i "'"Ma. t . A-- 187 14For possible usefulness of this exercise, see J. Johnston, Econometric Methods (New York:_ McGraw Hill Book Company, 1960). 15This indeed may be the case. A major form in which groundnuts are eaten domestically (and thus diverted away from the marketing board) is through roasting or frying of the nuts. It is not unlikely that consumption in this form falls as income rises. 16We assume that the disturbance, st, follows a E first order autoregressive scheme: at = pet_1 + Ut (t = 2,...,n) so that the transformed equation which is estimated with OLS to give (6)' above is: sa...-.-.—4q____ 1. . .4 1 . Y - pY _ = Bo(1-p) + 81(x2t - px2t_l) + 82(x3t - ) + Ut. px3t-l where 6 is the estimated autocorrelation coefficient from the residuals of (6). This method is only a special case of the iterative procedure suggested by Cochrane and Orcutt (see D. Cochrane and G. H. Orcutt, "Application of Least Squares Regressions to Relationships Containing Auto- correlated Error Terms," Journal of the American Statistical Association [March, 1949]). Our two stage procedure which does not go through the whole iterative procedure until convergence of the values of the estimates is attained does, however, possess the same asymptotic properties as the maximum likelihood estimators. Little is known about their small sample properties. See Kmenta, op. cit., p. 288. 17See the discussion on p. 103, especially footnote 2. 18The simple correlation coefficient between income and lagged groundnut price is 0.5280. 19This test is rather weak. The magnitude of the price change, the most recent history of relative prices . and the process by which Northern States farmers form and revise their expectations about future board prices are all relevant factors that are not captured by this test. 20See discussion on p. 63. 188 218. A. Oni, "Econometric Analysis of Supply Response Among Nigerian Cotton Growers," Bulletin of Rural Economics and Sociology (Ibadan: University of Ibadan, 1969). Oni's two estimates were .2069 and .2593 (see Ibid., p. 217). Assuming the change in sales per unit change in the board's price exceeds the corresponding change in output (production), then we expect our sales price elasticity to exceed the output (production) elasticity. This is likely to be so for most marketing board crops that have multiple market outlets. 22For possible reasons for the sign see p. 151. 23For reasons for including the trend variable, see p. 145. 24 See qualifications on p. 149, especially footnote 19. 25Not all cases of the transformation exercise on the groundnut equations are reported here. 26This mean figure was computed from the annual percentage figures reported in S. O. Olayide and Dupe Olatunbosun, "The Effect of the Marketing Boards on the Output and Income of Primary Producers," (NISER, 1971), p. 17. 27One alternative would have been to go further right of the mean percentage of world prices that was actually paid (mean [PNj/Pw]100 = 55.01%). The highest percentage of world prices farmers actually received in the sample period was 79.7 per cent in 1961. I could have then hypothesized a new price series with farmers receiving a percentage of world prices in each year in the neighborhood of 79.7 per cent. 1, therefore, constructed a price series on the assumption farmers received 70 per cent. .The maximum value in this series was LN 110.52 in 1951 and the minimum value was LN 27.61 in 1962. The mean of actual producer prices that farmers received (1950-67), the price series used in estimating the regression equations, was LN 33.38. There were only four years in which the hypo- thetical prices would have been below this mean; most of the other years, they were much higher (e.g., LN 62.14 in 1959, LN 56.58 in 1953, LN 55.14 in 1952, LN 110.52 in 1951, etc.). Thus, deviations from the mean of our original sample would have been very large. This would have made our predictions of sales to the board more I! ' fie -wu—1-. ._ ,. «nEZ! _l 189 imprecise. That is why I hypothesize a new price series in which we stay at 60 per cent of world prices but in which we avoid subperiods in which our hypothetical prices are lower than the actual prices farmers received. 28The total tax revenue figures are derived by multiplying the new predicted sales for a given year by the difference between the potential producer price (P ) and the new hypothetical Pfi° (= 60 per cent of world pfice). For the derivation of potential producer price in each year, see Table 4.3. There is an implicit assumption here and in all calculations of the revenue impact of new hypo- thetical prices that the change in sales induced by the new hypothetical prices does not affect the world price. Within the relevant price increases permitted with the new hypothetical prices, it is unlikely that the induced increase in sales will significantly affect world prices. 29This represents only the monetary income gain to farmers: real gains may not rise in the same proportion as incremental sales to the board lead to a reduction in the farmers' own home consumption. 30See footnote 28 for method of calculation. 31See footnote 28 for method of calculation. 32For the rationale behind this hypothesized pricing policy, see footnote 37. 33This mean percentage of potential producer price was calculated from H. C. Kriesel, "Cotton Marketing in Nigeria," CSNRD 24 (East Lansing: Michigan State Uni- versity, 1968), p. 73. 34For potential producer price figures see p. 109. 351 rejected the alternative of going further to the right of the actual mean (PN-/Pp) (mean (PNj/P ) = .846 for the period 1950-67) by choosing a higher 5Nj/pp ratio because this would have led to large positive deviations between our new hypothetical prices, Pfi° and the mean of the actual prices received (calculated to be PNj = 50.68) that were used to estimate the regression equation and this in turn would have increased the imprecision of our predictions. 190 36Though "both negative" is mathematically correct, we doubt its economic importance. 37When the third column is defined as the second column plus the first, it is: P -P’. ‘ p N: When the third column is derived from first principles, it is: (P — Pfij)M§ - (P - PNj)Mj. The two expressions are equiva ent. See p. 1 6. ) (M5 - Mj) - (Pfij - PNj) Mj 38These are calculated by multiplying the differ- ence between potential producer price (Pp) [for figures on this see Table 4.1] and the new higher price (Pfij) by the estimated sales (M5). 39See footnote 38 for method of calculation. 4OSee p. 144 and pp. 68-69 for reasons that may possibly lead to an underestimate of the sales price elasticity. 111:9 Ill. -.ln-’ .— ., - I CHAPTER VI MARKETING BOARDS AS POTENTIAL STABILIZERS OF STATE GOVERNMENT REVENUES Introduction Stabilization of producer prices or producer incomes was the original raison d'etre for the establishment of the marketing boards. With the emphasis shifting to the fiscal role of these boards, a new rationalization is emerging: that they can help stabilize State Government revenues. First, are (crop) tax revenues "stable?" What does our apriori knowledge tell us about the nature of factors influencing the supply and demand for these crops? What do these influences lead us to expect with respect to "stability" in volume of sales of crops to the boards? Second, can fluctuations in (crop) tax revenues offset fluctuations in State Government revenues from other sources apart from taxes on marketing board crops? The third objective of this study is to examine the extent to which reliance on revenue contributions from 191 192 marketing boards and allied statutory corporations can be trusted to stabilize State Government revenues. This chapter is divided into four sections. The first section examines total variance of revenue from taxes on marketing board crops; the second section looks at the relationship between numbers of crops and stabilization of average revenue yield per crop: in the third section, total variance of (crop tax) revenue is minimized subject "“"*“‘*"“‘m ’ J to certain constraints while the fourth section looks at variances and covariances of total State Government revenues with and without revenue contributions from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations. Marketing Boards as Potential _Siabflizers gffiate Government Revenue It has recently been suggested that "one important fiscal implication of the regionalization of the marketing boards is their conversion from potential stabilizers of producer prices into potential stabilizers of Regional Government revenue.1 This potential is implicitly recognized in Helleiner's strong advocacy for the fiscal role of marketing boards. This is a very important issue because in it lies a potentially powerful new justification for widening the taxing powers of the marketing boards. Many State Government Agricultural Officers did suggest widening the powers of the marketing boards at the (summer) 1971 Seminar of the National Agricultural Development 193 Committee held at the University of Ibadan. Is the revenue stabilizing potential of marketing boards real? Suppose stabilization means minimizing deviations from the mean revenue of the State Government over a given plan period so that a factor will be stabilizing if it reduces the variance of total State Government recurrent and capital revenue over a projected plan period of some years into the future. Let total revenue from taxes on m marketing board crops over the given plan period be the sum of revenues from taxes on the m individual crops, i.e., m R= 2: R. = 2t.M. (1) where R is total revenue from taxes on all marketing board crops within a given State over the projected State Development plan period; Rj is the total revenue from taxes on the jth crop over the plan period; tj is the unit tax rate (e.g., LN per ton) on the jth crop assumed constant to simplify arithmetic; Mj is total sales of the jth crop to the board over the plan period. From the point of view of the State Government and the marketing board, sales of any crop to the board can assume any positive value in any given year or when the whole plan period is considered. For all practical purposes then, given the uncertainty about the volume of sales of a given crop over the plan period, this volume of sales to the marketing board can be treated as a random variable. Therefore, total revenue 9» ~ 51"“1-‘1‘E' _ ‘ . I 194 accruing to the State Government and its marketing board from taxes on marketing board crops is also a random variable.2 The variance of total (crop) tax revenue is:3 m V(R) = Z 0.. t. t. (2) i.j=1 ‘3 1 3 where Oij is the covariance between the sales of the ith crop and sales of the jth crop to the marketing board and where we have, for simplicity, regarded the unit taxes as constants. Thus the variance of revenue from taxes on marketing board crops depends on the levels of taxes, the variances of sales of individual crops and the covariances between sales of all the crops. For given positive corre- lations between sales of crops, the higher the variances of individual crops, the higher the variance of total crop tax revenue. When the sales of all crops to the marketing board of a given State are independent of one another, then the covariance matrix of sales of these crops is the diagonal matrix with the ith diagonal element being the variance of sales of the ith crop to the board over the plan period and the variance of total revenue from taxes on all m crops is: ‘1‘“,- . h. 1:. ' 195 m V(R) = Z t. c. (3) where a; is the variance of sales of the jth crop to the board. Thus in the case where the covariance matrix of sales of all crops under marketing board control to the board is the diagonal matrix either because the sales are mutually uncorrelated or because they are independent, then it follows that the more crops are brought under the control of the board the greater the (absolute) variance of total revenue from taxes on these marketing board crops.4 The same result follows if all the off-diagonal elements of the covariance matrix were positive. If some or all of the off-diagonal elements cf the covariance1 matrix of sales to the board were negative, then it is possible to reduce total variance in (crop tax) revenue by bringing more crops under marketing board control. With non-independence among sales of crops to a marketing board (or with negative correlation coefficients), stability of State Government revenue from revenue con- tributions of marketing board crops is therefore determined by the magnitudes of the correlation coefficients and the size of the diagonal elements. Suppose public authorities are interested, not in the variance of total crop tax revenue, but in the variance of some "average tax revenue yield per crop." r-‘x- nu n—‘~_--._- 196 Let the State Government expect from its marketing board and allied statutory corporations a sum equal to the arithmetic mean of total revenue from taxes on m marketing board crops equal to R:5 - l R=-<2R) m j=1 j where R. is total tax revenue from the jth marketing board I - i1. '7‘ gym. {91:1}... e—-—-—. ‘ . l . 4 J crop.6 The variance of this is: -— 12m2 V(R) = (a) .5 OR. + 2 Zi 1, then revenue contributions during the plan period would actually destabilize State Government revenue; if OR: /c§ = 1, then revenue con- tributions from the marketing board and allied statutory corporations would contribute nothing to the stability of State Government revenue in the plan period, i.e., 2 O I S - 5 _ 0 ——§ 3 1 according as 0R2 3 2 R (10) o 0 Z Z f h' h 'f o - 0 th ch/o2 5 1 d' S l rom.w 1c 1 R — Z' en, Z 3 accor ing as 0R2 3.5 From equation (9) civil servants in state governments and academicians who believe or advocate the revenue stabi— - lizing role of marketing boards and allied statutory corporations would be most delighted if OR = oz and 9R2 = —1 because this would be saying that the variance of state 207 government revenue over the plan period inclusive of revenue contributions (loans and grants) from the board and allied statutory corporations is zero. Factors causing fluctu- ations in their revenue contributions include the many random factors that influence planned output of crops I (weather, technological uncertainty, etc.) and the many factors which influence planned sales to the marketing board (demand conditions in the country, demand conditions in neighboring countries, expected relative crop prices in these markets, etc.). The factors influencing State Government revenue exclusive of revenue contribution of boards and allied corporations include those factors that influence the revenue yield of personal income taxes and other direct taxes, Federal Government allocations that actually materialize, etc. It is only by accident that these sets of factors will operate in such a way as to = o render a The more responsive sales to the board of Z. a marketing board crop are to changes in demand conditions R on the home market and in neighboring countries, the larger would be the fluctuations of the revenue con- tributions of the marketing board and allied statutory corporations and therefore the more likely that State Government revenue would be destabilized. There is growing evidence that reliance on revenue contributions from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations is actually destabilizing State Government 208 revenues and plan budget operations. For the 1971/72 Budget Year for the Western State, Capital receipts of some LN 7 mill fell LN 5 mill short of estimates because the state of world markets, particularly for cocoa, made it impossible for the marketing board to make a contribution. . . . The Governor, Brigadier C. O. Rotimi, said that prospects for the coming year were better, although cocoa prices remained low and they still had to deal with smuggling, food shortage and inflation. . . .12 For most other marketing board crops including cotton and groundnuts, the factors making it "impossible for the marketing board to make a contribution" and thus leading to capital receipts falling short of estimates include an increasing diversion or sale of large quantities of these crops to the Nigerian domestic market through private marketing channels, the increasing amount of smuggling across Nigerian borders as expected relative crop prices in neighboring countries have been consistently higher than Nigerian marketing board prices and also increasing on-farm consumption by the farmers themselves. Reliance on marketing board revenue contributions has also destabilized revenues of statutory corporations especially when marketing boards made so-called trading losses. Thus, in the Eastern States in the 1950's, In order to enable the Production Development Boards to plan their programmes more effectively the Oil Palm Produce Marketing Board guaranteed them a minimum allocation of LN 800,000 for each of the years 1950-55. . . . In order to fulfil this obligation during its two years of trading losses it was necessary actually to reduce reserves which were not originally to be employed'for developmentgpurposes at all.13 209 From our earlier analysis, positive correlation between a State Government's revenues exclusive of any revenue contributions from its marketing board and allied statutory corporations and revenue contributions of these agencies would indicate that these contributions do indeed 7' tend to destabilize total State Government revenue, i.e., a— ‘ 571:9”- ). i 9 when State Government revenues from all other sources apart from the marketing boards and corporations tend to tn! Um‘-—-—-—. I fall, the revenue contributions of the board and corpo- rations also tend to fall and conversely for a tendency towards a rise. The empirical evidence supports the view that reliance on revenue contributions from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations has destabilized State Government revenues for all the states in the 1950's and 1960's. For the Northern States, this correlation coefficient was .6286 (pRz = .6286); for Western Nigeria, = .0171; for the Eastern States, = .7049. 0R2 pRz Implied in our earlier analysis is the fact that reliance on revenue contributions from the marketing board and allied corporations has the greatest potential for destabilizing State Government revenue when: first the crop has a large (and fluctuating) domestic market and/or markets in neighboring countries and secondly, the crop does not have significant irreversibilities in the investment-disinvestment process underlying its pro- duction.14 We would expect, therefore, that the State 210 Government relying on tax revenues from a crop subject to the most uncertain influences on the demand side and the least irreversibilities in the underlying investment— disinvestment process to be subject to the greatest danger of destabilization of State Government revenue, and the State Government relying on tax revenues from a crop subject to the least uncertain influences on the demand side and the greatest irreversibilities in the underlying investment-disinvestment process to be least exposed to the danger of destabilization of State Government revenue. This indeed is the case. The Western State, relying on revenue contributions from taxes on cocoa, had the least potential for destabilization (the most potential for stabilization) with, pRz = .0171; the Eastern States, relying on revenue contributions from mainly palm oil and palm kernel, had the most potential for destabilization (the least potential for stabilization), with 9R2 = .7049, while the Northern States, relying on revenue contributions from cotton, groundnuts, beniseed, and soybeans, also had high potential for destabilization (low potential for stabilization), with pRz = .6286. Table 6.1 summarizes these findings. Summary and Conclusions This chapter has been mainly concerned with the problems of relying on revenue contributions from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations for purposes of 211 . u. . I»! m rill-19‘-.. Iqu’fl‘y;nl.l.u . % .mcowueuomuou pewaae use mpueoc mcwuexuee ecu scum coHuscuuucoo esce>em ecu mu m use mcoHuscHuucoo emecu mo ebumsHoxe mesce>em eueum Heuoe mu N .mcoHueuomuoo huousueum peuaae use mpueoc mcwuexuefi ecu Eoum ecouuscwuucoo esce>eu mo e>wmsaocu mesce>em eueum Heuoe mu ace oooo.H meow. Hmmb. m HNNN.N mmme.ou omem.ma m oooo.H swam. N vmmv.mn v~mm.mm N Ammawmmav oooo.e em eoom.ooe em neuenm sneunem oooo.H Heao. «amp. m mmsm.mm bmvm. «Hma.em m oooo.a Home. N mnem.me vmmo.me N Amoummmav oooo.H 9m mvmo.ooa em euuemuz cueumez oooo.a meme. bmmn. m mmwv.a monm.¢ nmmm.m m oooo.a comm. N mmmm.mm vamm.hm N Avonmmmav ooo.H am mmma.mv em meueum cuecuuoz m N am m N am eueum xuuuez cOuueHeuuoo eHmEHm xuuuez eoceuue>ouaeoceuue> e.mmmalwmma .ewuemuz .mcowueuomuoo pewaas use mpueom mcuuecuez Scum mucuuscwuucou esce>em unocuug use cuuz mesce>em eueum mo meoceuue>ou use meoceuue>ln.u.o memes 212 stabilizing State Government revenues. It was shown that when total crop tax revenue is considered, the variance of this revenue depends on variances and covariances of sales of crops to the board and the level of taxes. For the four main crops under the Northern States Marketing Board, it was found that for the period 1947/48-1969/70, sales to the board were all positively correlated. This positive correlation was probably mainly due to supply and demand . :11 -.._".. '““‘W vI considerations and other common influences within the general economy. These positive correlations and the large variances must have contributed to instability in expected total crop tax revenue from these crops. If there had been negative correlations between sales to the board at the all-states level, the additional taxation of new crops, particularly those with smaller variances in sales (to the board) than those now being taxed, might have reduced total (crop tax) revenue variance. The next step was to take account of the insti- tutional set up. The Northern States Marketing Board is responsible for five major crops: groundnuts, cotton, beniseed, soybeans, and palm produce. At the beginning of each season, it decides how much to be paid to farmers-- how much tax to levy on the producers of these crops. The board is perceived to have a desired level of total (crop tax) revenue. When it decides on annual producer prices for the various crOps, it is implicitly deciding the .——._c ‘k v A v . 213 proportions in which the desired total (crop tax) revenue will be shared by the crops. We then asked the question: how should this desired total (crop tax) revenue be shared between these crops so as to minimize the variance in crop tax revenue subject to the condition that the desired total (crop tax) revenue will indeed be raised or realized? E The weights (shares) for the five crops under the Northern f States Marketing Board (including here palm produce from : Idah, Ankpa, and Dekina Divisions) were found to be e- functions of the elements of the Jacobian matrix: the variances and covariances of individual crop tax revenues as well as the expected crop tax revenue from each crop, and the desired total (crop tax) revenue from the five crops. The final section of this paper looked at vari- ances and covariances of total State Government Revenues with and without revenue contributions from the marketing boards and allied statutory corporations. Our intuitive expectations were borne out by the empirical results. The Western State relying mainly on a perennial crop-- cocoa-~that is likely to be most subject to irreversi- bilities in the underlying investment-disinvestment process and also least subject to domestic demand fluctuations experienced the least destabilization of total state revenue through reliance on revenue contributions from the marketing board and allied statutory corporations. The 214 Eastern States relying on palm produce picked mainly from the wild trees--a crop least likely to be subject to irreversibilities on the supply side, but having a large and fluctuating domestic market--experienced the greatest destabilization in total state revenue through reliance on revenue contributions from the marketing board and allied statutory corporations. The Northern States relying mainly on annual crops--groundnuts, cotton, beniseed, and soybeans-~occupied middle ground between the Western and Eastern States. 7mm. . FOOTNOTES 10. Teriba and O. Olakanpo, "Fiscal, Monetary and Investment Implications of the Marketing Boards" (Inter- national Conference on the Marketing Board System, NISER, Ibadan, 1971), p. 10. 2 O O O O O R, being a linear combination of random variables, is also a random variable. 3S. S. Wilks, Mathematical Statistics (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1962). 4 . . . There may be some reduction in tax revenue vari- ance from reductions in some taxes. 5We can give meaning to the concept of an "average tax revenue yield per crop," R. First, different states have different numbers of marketing board crops and the concept is useful for interstate comparisons of crop tax yields. Second, an individual crop's tax revenue yield can be compared with the average for all crops. Third, the concept may be useful in decisions as to whether more or fewer crops should be brought under marketing board control (what does a marginal change in number of crops do to average cr0p tax revenue yield?). 6R, being a linear combination of random variables (the Rj's) is also a random variable. 7That increasing the number of crops tends to reduce V(R) can be seen in the case of mutual zero corre- lation from - m %_%i_1 = .53 2 02R < o (6') m i=1 i 215 216 Even in this case, the contribution of the ith new crop to V(R) which also depends on the variance of sales and therefore of revenue from taxes on this crop is given by: R. 1 0 m2 and given the present nature of demand and supply of Nigerian agricultural crops, any new crop to be taxed is likely to have large OZR- than those now being taxed. i 8This is only an analytic result with no obvious practical significance. 9The palm produce is mainly from Idah, Dekina, and Ankpa Divisions of Kwara State. 10This becomes evident from the following variance- covariance matrix of sales of cotton, groundnuts, beniseed, and soybeans to the Northern States Marketing Board, Nigeria, 1947/48-1969/70: Groundnut Sales 66,805,459,l38 Seed Cotton Sales 8,590,375,363 3,384,704,988 Beniseed Sales 1,091,769,796 91,429,158 59,513,615 Soybean Sales 239,623,846 22,762,873 21,791,670 47,608,633 Groundnut Seed Cotton Beniseed Soybean Sales Sales Sales Sales 11 Friedman, in his analysis of countercyclical policies has used this method. See M. Friedman, "The Effects of a Full-Employment Policy on Economic Stability: A Formal Analysis," in his Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953). Don Patinkin has argued in the February 1969 issue of the Journal of MoneyL_Credit and Banking that Friedman's 1956 essay, 1""'I‘rhe QuantityTheory--A Restatement" in M. Friedman, ed., Studies in the uantity Theory of Money (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956), is mistitled, on the grounds that Friedman's essay is an eloquent réiormulation of Keynesian liquidity theory that borrows heavily from the modern asset portfolio school headed by James Tobin. Patinkin's argument is convincing. Similarly, the title of Friedman's book, Essays in Positive Economics is mis- leading in the sense that there is hardly any unified (and meaningful) body of economics without substantial normative content. For a modern development of these 217 themes, see Glenn L. Johnson and Lewis K. Zerby, 152 Plates of Spaghetti (East Lansing: Michigan State Uni- versity); and Glenn L. Johnson, et al., A Generalized SimulationjApproach to Agricultural Sector Analysis With Special Reference to Nigeria (East Lansing: Michigan State University, November, 1971), Chapter X. 12See West Africa, #2865 (Apapa: Times Press, May 12, 1972), p. 587. (Emphasis in passage my own.) 13G. K. Helleiner, "The Fiscal Role of the Marketing Boards in Nigerian Economic Development, 1947-61," in C. K. Eicher and C. Leidholm, eds, Growth and Development of the Nigerian Econom (East Lansing: Michigan State UniverEity Press, 1970 , p. 129. (Emphasis in passage my own.) 14A third possible condition is the degree to which the marketing board is committed to the stabilization of the producer price of this crop. CHAPTER VII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS This study had three main aims: first to provide a framework for analyzing the effects of government and marketing board taxation on cotton and groundnuts in the Northern States on resource use in these crOps: second, to examine the quantitative impact of paying groundnut and cotton farmers higher prices on tax revenue from these crops and third, to examine the extent to which these crop tax revenues can be trusted to stabilize State Government revenue for planning purposes. It was shown (see Table 3.1, Chapter III) that government and marketing board taxes on cotton and ground- nuts introduced allocative distortions in the relative quantities of these crops produced in the Northern States during the period 1950-66, as farmers have substituted (in production) along given transformation curves in response to changing relative (crop) net producer prices induced by differential tax rates. With differential taxation of cotton and groundnuts detrimental to groundnuts, the relative quantity of cotton was higher than would have 218 219 been the case in the absence of all taxation, wherever cotton and groundnuts were substitutes in production. Implicit in the model is the fact that food crops, relative to cotton and groundnuts, were produced in quantities larger than would have been the case in the absence of all taxation since food crops bore zero rates of taxation and cotton and groundnuts bore (and still bear) positive rates of taxation most of the period examined, wherever food crops and these marketing board crops were substitutes in production. Taxes on marketing board crops have distorted patterns of specialization in Nigerian farming, either in terms of the production patterns for food and marketing board crops on the one hand or in terms of the production patterns of marketing board crops bearing different rates of taxation.1 A model was developed in Chapter III to explain the effects of these taxes on the scale of farming in the Northern States (1950-66), measured either in terms of acreage or labor. When the model was extended to account for the differential between off-farm acquisition and salvage values, the investment-disinvestment responses to changes in taxes and subsidies differed, in many cases, from those predicted by the neoclassiCal model that assumes equality between acquisition and salvage values for durable inputs. The empirical evidence on the effects of these taxes on resource use provided in Chapter III is revealing. 220 It was shown that cotton and groundnuts farms (acreage) in the Northern States are smaller than they would have been in the absence of taxation of marketing board crops. At a time when state governors and other policy makers are very concerned about the diversion of acreages away from marketing board crops to other crops, this is significant evidence indeed. As a result of these taxes, farmers have not found it profitable to expand acreages under cotton and groundnuts as fast as they would have done in the absence of these taxes. Strong logical reasons were also provided, based on the levels of taxes on cotton and groundnuts (1950-66), to show that the amounts of labor (family labor and hired labor) employed on Northern States cotton and groundnut farms during the period 1950-66 were lower than would have been the case in the absence of taxes on these crops. Not only were the stocks of these resources employed on these farms less than they would have been, but they were also worked less intensively than would have been the case in the absence of taxes on these crops. These taxes thus directly affect resource use as these relate to the underemployment and unemployment of human resources in rural areas. Marginal farms have been forced to close as a result of these taxes; people released from these marginal farms are induced to migrate to the towns by higher expected present value of life time earnings in the urban areas like metropolitan Kano, Zaria, Kaduna, Sokoto, and Lagos. 221 These adverse effects on resource use operate at two levels: first, taxes reduce acquisitions of labor and land below what they would have been in the absence of taxes and thus reduce the rate of entry of new resources into the farm sector and second, taxes induce salvaging and disinvestment of used resources on hand and thus increase the rate of exit of resources from the farm sector. These adverse effects implied by our analysis can be inferred from available empirical evidence for three reasons. First, even if resources are fixed with respect to off-farm acquisition and salvage values, they are allocated among competing crops according to their on-farm opportunity costs. Farmers are known to be reallocating these resources in response to the effects of taxes on these on-farm opportunity costs.2 Second, these resources are heterogeneous. Older farmers in response to taxes on marketing board crops may simply reallocate their skills between these crops and non-marketing board crops on the basis of their on-farm opportunity cost while younger farmers and rural farm youth may quit farming altogether and move to the urban centers3 when their off-farm market salvage values exceed their on-farm opportunity costs. Third, farms of different sizes are differently endowed with resources and have different initial quantities on hand. 222 With less resources being used as a result of these taxes, less cotton and groundnuts were produced (and presumably less was therefore sold to the marketing board) relative to the (profit maximizing) quantities of these crops that would have been produced in the absence of any taxes on them. This has obvious implications for those states that have production campaigns for marketing board crops in their development plans. Suppose a state wishes to increase its production (output) of a marketing board crop (e.g., cotton, groundnuts) by a given annual percentage for each year of the development plan. Starting with a production function, we can express the percentage increase in the output of the marketing board crOp as the weighted sum of the percentage increases in the resources used to produce this crop, where the weights are the output elasticities of these resources.4 For given output elasticities of these resources, the annual percentage increase in the output of the marketing board crop is higher, the higher the percentage increases in the quantities of resources used to produce this crop. To the extent that taxes on marketing board crOps have impeded annual percentage increases in resources used in the production of marketing board crops, they have consequently impeded the rate of growth of output of these crops. The evidence in Chapter III implies that this must have been the case (see pp. 58-59. 223 The last part of Chapter III was of the nature of providing policy makers with a policy variable: given that labor and land produce the bulk of value added in Nigerian agriculture and if we are willing to assume the institutional reality of the marketing boards, then, if State planners wish to minimize the allocative distortions with respect to the use of land and labor introduced by these taxes, what are the compensating subsidies on fertilizers, chemicals, land, labor, etc.? It was shown that these compensating subsidies are related to the out- put elasticities of these resources. Using a Cobb-Douglas production function and the available estimates on the output elasticity of land, it was calculated that to keep the acreage in groundnuts production from falling, given a l per cent decrease in the net producer price of ground- nuts received by farmers, then, the net acquisition price of land that groundnuts farmers have to pay has to fall by 2.931? per cent. In cotton production, the corresponding compensating subsidy is 1.8860 per cent. It was also calculated that to keep the quantity of labor employed in groundnuts production from falling, given a l per cent decrease in the net producer price of groundnuts received by farmers, then the net acquisition price of land that groundnut farmers have to pay has to fall by 2.746 per cent. In cotton production, the corresponding compensating subsidy is 2.422 per cent. In this way, programs for 224 subsidies on resources used in Northern States farming in the future can be rationally related to expected tax rates on the crops in which these resources are employed. If resources are fixed where their MVP's are between their off-farm market acquisition and salvage values, small taxes have no effect on resource employment and thus would require no compensating subsidies. Large taxes will lead to disinvestment which may be necessary until resources are being employed at levels where acquisition costs are being covered. The link between the response of tax revenue from cotton and groundnuts to producer price changes and the response of sales of these crOps to the board to changes in the net producer price was established in Chapter IV. The more reSponsive sales of a crop (to the board) are to changes in its price, the more responsive (in absolute value) is tax revenue to these producer price changes (see pp. 105-113). The illustrative calculations in Chapter IV using actual data on taxes and net producer prices for the period 1950-66 bring out clearly the link between the elasticity of (crop tax) revenue with respect to producer prices paid out by the board and the elasticity of sales (to the board) with respect to the board's net producer prices: the more elastic sales to the board are of a crop with respect to its net producer price, the more elastic (in absolute value) is the tax revenue from this crOp with respect to the board's net producer price for 225 the crop (see Tables 4.1-4.4). Attempts to raise more (tax) revenue from a crop by paying producers lower prices might become self-defeating if sales of this crOp to the board are very price responsive or even moderately price responsive. In the last section of Chapter IV, it was argued that when long run influences are considered, questions about the (tax) revenue potential of marketing board crops and the farm sector as a whole depend impor- tantly on the crop price response of the underlying investment-disinvestment process. In the first section of Chapter V, we sketched a simultaneous equation system in which the sales supply equation was one of four structural equations. Previous econometric treatments of sales (to the board) of marketing board crops have not provided any system structure of which the sales supply equation was only one component. The system incorporates our apriori knowledge of the factors influencing the sale of a crop to the board. Identi- fiability of the sales supply relation was then investigated after which reduced form solutions for the endogenous variables of the system were derived. Availability of data would then have permitted two-stage least squares estimation of the (structural) sales supply equation. A modified model which removes obvious sources of biasedness and inconsistency from our ordinary least squares estimates of the parameters of single sales supply 226 equations for groundnuts and cotton was then estimated. The elasticity of sales of groundnuts to the Northern States Marketing Board with respect to the board's producer price was estimated to be 1.3139 and that of cotton to be .90278. It was then postulated that farmers were to be paid (on the average) higher prices than they actually received (1950-67). Predictions of sales were made, on the basis of the estimated equations, using the postulated hypothetical prices. It was found for both cotton and groundnuts that when the postulated prices were higher than actual prices the board paid the farmers, predicted sales were higher than actual sales. The predicted sales incorporating the "price effect" on sales and the implied lower taxes were then used to show the quantitative impact of (generally) higher producer prices on tax revenue from these two crops. It was shown that in many years with the new higher producer prices, farmers would have gained substantially in monetary income without the government and marketing board being significantly worse off in revenue terms (where "significantly worse off" is defined in terms of net (tax) revenue loss relative to new total tax revenue). For cotton, with the postulated new higher prices in 1951, farmers would have gained LN l,0?l,7l7.6 in monetary income; total (tax) revenue incorporating the positive effect of higher prices on cotton sales would 227 have been LN 3,248,801.3.5 The net loss in (crop tax) revenue would have been LN 463,684.4 (see Table 5.12), thus leaving the government and marketing board a positive net (crop tax) revenue balance of LN 2,785,116.9. Thus, total net revenue would not have been significantly affected.6 Further, when this is compared with the total tax with— drawals of LN 1,742,2007 from cotton in 1951 using actual producer prices and actual sales that were both lower than the hypothetical price and the predicted sales respectively that were used in the above computations, it is evident that the government and the marketing board were not significantly worse off revenue-wise paying farmers higher prices than the prices actually paid. In 1957, with farmers receiving (the new) higher prices, they would have gained LN 460,930.l in monetary income while the government and the marketing board would have lost LN 712,147.l (see Table 5.12). Total tax revenue from cotton in this year after incorporating the positive effect of higher prices on sales was calculated to be LN l,034,927.5,8 thus leaving a net (crop tax) revenue of LN 322,780.4. Relative to the actual total tax revenue of LN 77,6009 using actual prices and actual sales, the government and marketing board were better off, revenue-wise.10 For groundnuts in 1954, with the postulated new higher prices, farmers would have gained LN 2,683,987.2 in monetary income. The government and the Northern States 228 Marketing Board would have suffered a net revenue loss of LN 988.142.0 (see Table 5.8): in the same year incorporating the positive effect of higher prices on sales, total tax revenue from groundnuts was calculated to be LN 5,125,384.4, thus leaving a net tax withdrawal from groundnuts of 11 LN 4,337,242.4. The net loss in total (crop tax) revenue 12 In 1950 and 1951, the net is not very significant. losses in (crop tax) revenue were significant. For the other years for both groundnuts and cotton, there are varying degrees of offsets of revenue loss by the positive effect of higher prices on sales. On the average, the net revenue losses do not appear to be very substantial, relative to the new total tax revenues and the gain in monetary income to farmers. Any assessment of the total effects of taxation of marketing board crops must take into account the effects on production (output) of the crop and the effects on its sales to the board. Chapter III provided indirect evidence on production by examining the effects of these taxes on resource use. To the extent that resources were being employed on a smaller scale than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes, then production (out- put) was less than would have been the case in the absence of taxes on these crops. The estimates and predictions of Chapter V showed that sales of crops to the board were lower than would have been the case if the board paid 229 farmers higher prices. We were not able to take the production effect of these taxes into account directly because of lack of data on total output of any of the crops treated. This production effect of these taxes would then have been incorporated in our analysis of the impact on (crop tax) revenue of paying farmers higher (hypothetical) prices. It is hoped that this shortcoming will be remedied as data on total output of these crops become available. The CSNRD series were a landmark in studying the effects of marketing board taxation of Nigerian agriculture. We have extended these studies by explicitly specifying, identifying and estimating the sales supply relation for marketing board crops as a basis for estimating the quantitative impact on tax revenue from these crops of paying farmers higher prices and also by explicitly treating the resource employment effects of these taxes. The major justification for the past and present roles of marketing boards has been their potential ability to stabilize producer prices and producer incomes. Their success in this regard has not concerned us in this study. Their potential for stabilizing State Government revenues is the newly emerging rationale for not only retaining these boards but also for widening their taxing powers. Treating sales to the board of any cr0p as a random vari- able, it is shown in Chapter VI that the (State Government) revenue stabilizing potential of marketing boards and 230 allied statutory corporations is very small. In the case of total revenues from taxes on all crops within marketing board control, it is shown that the variance of total revenue depends largely on the elements of the covariance matrix of sales to the board of these crops. Arguments and empirical evidence are used to show that not only are the diagonal elements of this covariance matrix large, but that the off-diagonal elements are likely to be positive. In this case, the larger the number of crOps under the board's control, the larger the variance in tax revenues. Using crops under the control of the Northern States Marketing Board as an example, it was found that the correlation coefficient between groundnut sales and cotton sales to the board over the period 1947-1970 was .5713, between grounduts sales and beniseed sales .5475, between groundnut sales and soybeans sales .1344, between seed cotton sales and beniseed sales .2037, between beniseed sales and soybeans sales .4094 and the least correlation coefficient (still positive!) was that between seed cotton sales and soybeans sales, .0567. The variances of sales of groundnuts, cotton, beniseed, and soybeans were respectively: 166,805,459,138.30, 3,384,704,988.6l, $9,513,615.71, and 47,608,633.87. Thus, the variances of sales to the board are large; and their covariances are also large and positive. Thus, the potential for stabi- lizing total revenue by increasing the taxing powers of the boards is small for the present composition of 231 marketing board crops in the Northern States. Most of the variation in tax revenues from these crops is likely to come not from variations in tax rates on these crops but from variations in sales of these crOps to the board. Using sales as a proxy for revenue, we found that the average covariance of sales for the four marketing board crops of the Northern States (1947-40/1969-70) was 1,676,292,118.28. If the average covariance of (tax) revenues from these crops is some (nondecreasing) linear function of this, then prospects for stabilizing State Government revenues from reliance on marketing boards and allied statutory corporations are very small indeed. Using actual budget figures for the Northern States, the Eastern States and the old Western Region, it was also shown that reliance on revenue contributions from marketing boards and allied statutory corporations destabilized State Government revenues. It was argued that such reliance was potentially destabilizing when, first, the crop has a large (and fluctuating) domestic market and/or markets in neighboring countries and second, when the crOp does not have significant irreversibilities in the underlying 13 The old Western investment-disinvestment process. Region, relying on revenue contributions from taxes on cocoa--a perennial crop--had the least potential for destabilization (the most potential for stabilization) of State Government revenue. The correlation coefficient between State Government revenues in the absence of 232 contributions from the marketing board and allied statutory corporations and revenue contributions from them for the period 1956-66 (i.e., PRZ) was .0171. The Eastern States relying on revenue contributions from taxes mainly on palm oil and palm kernels had the most potential for destabili- zation (the least potential for stabilization) of State Government revenue. The corresponding correlation coef- ficient (PR2) for the Eastern States for the period 1956-65 was calculated to be .7049. The Northern States, relying mainly on revenue contributions from taxes on cotton, soy- beans, groundnuts, and beniseeds--all annual crops--occupied the middle ground between the Eastern States and the old Western Region. Such reliance had high potential for destabilization (low potential for stabilization) of State Government revenues. The corresponding correlation coef- ficient (PRZ) for-the Northern States for the Period 1956-64 was calculated to be .6286.14 Implications of Findings For the past two decades, some form of price or income stabilization role for producers has been used to justify the existence of marketing boards. There is still no conclusive evidence that marketing boards have succeeded in this regard. A new emerging role is that of state revenue stabilization. Our analysis in Chapter VI indi— cated that the potential of marketing boards and allied statutory corporations as stabilizers of State Government 233 revenues is almost nil. Unless a new cogent reason is found, we find it difficult to justify the present marketing structure.15 Unemployment is currently a major problem in Nigeria. It was shown in Chapter III that taxes on marketing board crops have distorted the relationships between on-farm and off-farm opportunity costs of labor, and, by implication, that the ratio of the present values of the latter to the former is higher than would have been the case in the absence of these taxes. This has induced the drift of people from the rural to the urban areas. Any attempt to arrest this drift must seriously consider 16 The high social costs the elimination of these taxes. of artificially induced unemployment of people in the urban areas can then be minimized or avoided. The existence of these taxes is one major reason why cotton and groundnut farms are small. It is possible for most farmers in cotton and groundnut production to increase their acreages in these crops if it is profitable. In the Report of the Study Group on Groundnuts it is stated: "In some parts of the North, particularly in the North Eastern State, substantial areas of land are unused at present and could be available for expansion of groundnuts."17 If the increased acreages are to be forthcoming, these taxes must be drastically reduced or eliminated. 234 A current problem is the transformation of Northern States agriculture from one relying mainly on traditional inputs to one that employs new and superior inputs. This 18 The demand transformation is proceding rather slowly. for new inputs has been adversely affected by taxes on marketing board crops. A minimum requirement in the presence of these taxes is the urgent need for compensating subsidies on resources to minimize allocative distortions introduced by these taxes. It was shown in Chapter III that these compensating subsidies are related to the output elasticities of these resources used in production. In this way, programs in State Development Plans and production campaign projects for subsidizing chemicals, fertilizers, insecticides, land, skilled labor, etc., can rationally be related to expected taxes on the crOps in which these resources are used. We do expect structural changes like improved transportation network and improved marketing information about crop prices in different parts of the country. These changes will raise the elasticity of sales (to the board) of a marketing board crop with respect to the board's net producer price for the crop. Such changes may indeed render policies that seek to raise (tax) revenue by paying farmers lower prices self-defeating. FOOTNOTES 1See pp. 26-27 for evidence and discussion on the policy of self-sufficiency in cotton being pursued by the Western State. 2From our apriori knowledge of the ease with which labor and land are shifted between crops in the cotton- groundnuts-foods economy of the Northern States, we infer that the allocation of fixed resources must be on the basis of their on-farm opportunity costs. Let us see the effects of taxes on this opportunity costs. Suppose labor of a given age and skill is fixed in the sense that it does not pay to invest or disinvest in it. Let this fixed labor (L ) be allocated between groundnuts (G) and food pro- duction (F). The farmer's production function is, in implicit form, f (L, G, F) = 0 (1)' which can be written explicitly as L0 = f(G, F) Let the farmer then maximize his revenue from food and groundnut production subject to the constraint that he has this fixed amount of labor to allocate between them. Form the Lagrangian. — o- L — PFF + (uGPG)G + alL f(G, F)] where PF and PG are food and groundnut prices respectively and “G is the proportion of potential producer price of groundnuts paid by the board to farmers. The necessary conditions for equilibrium are a:._ _ af_ fi-% “fi-0 3L at $3 235 236 EL _ o from which a _ Pf _ uGPG “W“? 6'5 from which it follows that a = PF %% = “GPG %% where 3F and as are the marginal products of labor in food and groundnut production respectively and a, the unde- termined Lagrangian multiplier, turns out to be the on- farm opportunity cost of labor. Without any taxes, pg = 1. With an increase in taxes on groundnuts, o < “G < l, and there is induced reallocation of labor away from groundnut to food production until, in equilibrium, the opportunity cost of labor in food and groundnut production is the same. Fixity of a resource does not therefore preclude these allocative responses in resource use to taxes on marketing board crops. 3In a June issue of West Africa, it is stated: "A total of 72,000 tons of grouhdnuts were produced in the North Eastern State in 1970-71 compared with 204,000 tons the previous season. Cotton production fell from 86,000 tons to 40, 000 tons. The State Commissioner for Agri- culture and Cooperatives, Alhaji Muhammadu Mai, attributed the decline to the drift of farmers to the towns. . . See West Africa, #2871 (Apapa: Times Press, June 23, 1972). CompIaints about the "drift of farmers" to the towns are very frequent these days among state governors. It is evident that taxes on marketing board crops have distorted the relative magnitudes of the mean present values of marginal value products of these farmers on Nigerian farms and the expected present values of their off-farm oppor- tunity costs in the urban areas. It is perfectly rational for these farmers to migrate in the face of these taxes on marketing board crops. 4Writing the production function as: Yj = f(Xl' eeee' Xn)’ it is evident that AY. n AX. __1 z e __1 Y O I Y O X I x 3 i=1 j i i 237 where Y is the quantity of the jth marketing board crop produced with the resources X1, ..., Xn, - is the elasticity of output of the jth crop with Eraspect to the ith resource, AYj is the percentage change in Yj and AXi Yj Xi is the percentage change in xi! (1 = l, ..., n). 5For the method used to calculate total tax revenue incorporating the positive effect of higher prices on sales, see footnote 6Net (tax) revenue loss is 14 per cent of the new total (tax) revenue. 7For this figure on total tax revenue using actual producer prices and actual sales, see G. K. Helleiner, Peasant Agriculture, Government and Economic Growth in Nigeria (Irwin, 1966), Table V-F- 5. 8See footnote 38. 9For this figure, see Helleiner, o . cit. 10However, with net (tax) revenue loss 68 per cent of the new total tax revenue, government and marketing board tax revenue is significantly affected. 11For method of calculating this figure, see p. 189. 12The net loss in tax revenue is 19 per cent of new total (crop tax) revenue. 13See discussion on p. 221, especially footnote 2. 14These relative performances of the states are consistent with our apriori expectations. Cocoa is a perennial crop and therefore most likely to have sub- stantial irreversibilities in the investment—disinvestment process underlying its production; it also has very little domestic demand in the form sold to the board. The bulk of the palm oil and kernels sold to the board comes from wild palm trees, thus making it possible to adjust rapidly to price changes. Palm oil has a large (and fluctuating) domestic market and neighboring country market demand. Cotton and groundnuts occupy middle ground between cocoa and palms both in terms of expected irreversibilities 238 underlying their production as well as the size of the domestic and neighboring country market conditions. 15It might be tempting to play down on the need for the extended discussion here given to this issue, on the grounds that petroleum revenues will do the job of stabilization. The present value of petroleum revenues is certainly bounded by the nonreplenishable nature of the resource. Even in the face of the present petroleum revenue boom, not all revenue needs of all states can be met. State Governments continue to seek sources of revenue independent of the Federal Government. Marketing boards are a good source of revenue and given the exposure of the myth that these boards are there to stabilize prices and incomes and help farmers, marketing board advocates are searching for new justifications for the existence of marketing boards. We must avoid replacing old myths with new ones. It should also be recognized that we have not examined other sources of State Government revenues in terms of "stability." Stability might not be important for some purposes, but is vital for state budgetary operations and is important as a potential justification for the existence of the marketing boards. 16The Governor of Lagos State, Colonel M. Johnson recently called on other State Governments to help him stem the outflow of people from their states into his own state. The Governor will go a long way toward solving this problem if he seriously encourages these State Govern- ments to abolish the present marketing board system. See West Africa (Apapa: Times Press, May-June, 1972). 17See Report of the Study Group on Groundnuts (Lagos: Federal Department of’Agriculture, 1971), p. 13. 18Ibid. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY P. T. West African Trade. London: Cambridge University Press, 1954. Economic Analysisgnd Policy in Underdeveloped Cambridge University Press, Bauer, Countries. London: Markets, Market Control and , and B. S. Yamey. __ Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1968. MarketinggReform. Supplngesponse in Underdeveloped Agriculture. North-Hoiiand Publishing Company, 1968. Behrman, J. Amsterdam: Bishop, C. "The Effects of Specific and Ad Valorem Taxes." Quarterly_Journal of Economics (1968). Cochrane, D., and G. H. Orcutt. "Applications of Least Squares Regressions to Relationships Containing Autocorrelated Error Terms." Journal of the American Statistical Association (March, 1949). Statistics and Econometrics. New York: Frank, C. R. Inc., 1971. Holt, Rinehart and Winston, "The Effects of a Full-Employment Policy on A Formal Analysis." In Chicago: University Friedman, M. Economic Stability: Essays in Positive Economics. of Chicago Press, 1953. E. "Optimal Farm Size." American Journal of Agri- Heady, cultural Economics (February, 1971). Peasant Agriculture, Government and Helleiner, G. K. Richard Irwin, Inc., Economic Growth in Nigeria. T966. . "The Fiscal Role of the Marketing Boards in Nigerian Economic Development," In C. K. Eicher and C. Liedholm, eds., Growth and Development of the Nigerian Economy. East Lansing: Michigan State University Press, 1970. 239 240 Johnson, Glenn L. "The State of Agricultural Supply Analysis." Journal of Farm Economics (May, 1960). . "Supply Function--Some Facts and Notions," In E. O. Heady, H. G. Diesslin, H. R. Jensen, and G. L. Johnson, Agricultural Ad'ustment Problems in a Growing Economy. Ames: Iowa State CoIlege Press, 1958. . "Capital," In International Encyclopeida of the Social Sciencee. The MacMilian Company aha the Free Press, 1968. ' ' . "Factor Markets and the Problem of Economic Development." In W. W. McPherson, ed., Economic Develo ment of Tro ical Agriculture. University of FIoriaa Press, 1968. . "Review of Nerlove." Agricultural Economic Research (January, 1960). , and Leroy Quance. The Overproduction Trep in American A riculture. The Johns Hopkins University Press, 19 2. , O. J. Scoville, G. K. Dike, and C. K. Eicher. Strategies and Recommendations for Ni erian Rural Development, 1969-1985. Consortium or the Study of Nigerian Rural Development (CSNRD) 33, Michigan State University, East Lansing, 1969. , and L. K. Zerby. What Economists Do About Values: Case Studies of and Answers to Questions They Don't Dare Ask. East Lansing: Michigan State UhiverSity, 1971. , et a1. Managerial Processes ofMidwestern Farmers. Iowa State University Press, 1961. , et al. A Generalized Simulation Approach to Agricultural Sector AnalySis With Special Appli- cation to Nigeria. East Lansing: MiEhigan State University, 1971. Johnson, H. G. "Towards a Generalized Capital Accumulation Approach to Economic Development," In M. Blaug, Economics of Education 1. Penguin Books, 1968. Johnston, J. Econometric Methods. New York: McGraw Hill Book Company, 1960. 241 Kmenta, Jan. Elements of Ecopometrics. New York: MacMillan Company,_197l. Kriesel, H. The Marketing of Groundnuts in Nigeria. East Lansing: CSNRD l9,Michigan State University, 1968. . Cotton Marketing_in Nigeria. East Lansing: CSNRD 24, Michigan State University, 1968. Laurent, C. K. Problems Facing the Fertilizer Distribution Program in the Six Northern States. East Lansing: CSNRD 27, Michigan State UniVersity, 1969. Malinvaud, E. Statistical Methods of Econometrics. 2nd revised ed. Amsterdam-London: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1970. Musgrave, R. The Theor of Public Finance. New York: McGraw Hill, 1 59. Nigeria, Federal Ministry of Information. Second National Development Plan 1970-74. Lagos: 1970. , Federal Department of Agriculture. Report of the Studngroup on Cotton and Other Fibres. Lagos: 1971. . Report of the Study Group on Groundnuts. 1971. . Report of the Study Group on Oil Palms. 1971. , Federal Office of Statistics. Annual Abstract of Statistics (various issues); Digest of_Sta- tistics (variOus issues). Norman, D. W. An Economic Study of Three Vilieges in Zaria Province. Vol. 1, Part II. Zaria: Samaru Miscel- laneous Paper, Ahmadu Bello University, 1970. . "Initiating Change in Traditional Agriculture." Zaria: R.E.R.U., Ahmadu Bello University, 1970. Northern Nigeria, Ministry of Economic Planning, Kaduna. Northern Nigeria Statistical Yearbook 1966. Olatunbosun, D., and S. O. Olayide. "The Effects of the Marketing Boards on the Output and Income of Primary Producers." Ibadan: NISER, 1971. 242 Patinkin, Don. "The Chicago Tradition, the Quantity Theory and Friedman." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking (February, 1969i. Samuelson, P. Foundations of Economic Analysis. New York: Atheneum, 1965. Schultz, T. W. Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Yale University Press, 1964. Standard Bank Ltd., Nigeria. Annual Economic Review (various issues). Stigler, G. "Notes on Duopoly." Journal of Political Economy (1940). Teriba, O., and O. Olakanpo. "Fiscal, Monetary and Investment Implications of the Marketing Boards." Ibadan: NISER, 1971. Tintner, G. Econometrics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1952. Titiloye, M. O., and A. A. Ismail. "A Survey of the Trends and Problems in the Domestic Arrangements for the Marketing of Groundnuts and Cotton." Ibadan: NISER, 1971. Ulveling, E. "Comment." American Journal of Agricultural Economics (February, 1972). West Africa. Apapa: Times Press. Western Nigeria, Ministry of Economic Planning and Reconstruction. Western State Development Plan, 1970-74. Ibadan: I971. Wilks, S. Mathematical Statistics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 196 . "711111111171111.1111711“