1mminimumlulllllllllll'" "“ 3 1293 104 6 This is to certify that the thesis entitled STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION IN THE ECONOMY OF PUERTO RICO FROM 1940 TO 1972: AN INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS presented by Samuel Torres Roman has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Philosophy 0-7 639 MSU LIBRARIES u RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to remove this checkout from your record. [lfl§§ will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION IN THE ECONOMY OF PUERTO RICO FROM 1940 TO 1972: AN INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS By Samuel Torres Roman A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1978 ABSTRACT STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION IN THE ECONOMY OF PUERTO RICO FROM 1940 TO 1972: AN INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS By Samuel Torres Roman In this study the structural transformation of the economy of Puerto Rico from 1940 to 1972 is examined to determine how the changes have affected the capacity to main- tain self-sustained growth. Puerto Rico has been transformed from the colonial agricultural economy of 1940 into a modern industrial economy, with the help of a government "Bootstrap" program to attract private investment using various incentives. The rate of economic growth was remarkable up to 1972, but stagnatedafter that year. The unemployment rate never fell below llpercent in the best years, in spite of rapid growth in the gross national product and a hugh migration to the United States. After 1972 unemployment increased steadily, reaching 20 per- cent in 1977. The possible causes of the recent stagnation are investigated by looking into the way structural changes Samuel Torres Roman during transition have affected the capacity of the Puerto Rican economy to create output and to generate employment in a self-reinforcing process. The method of study was a historical, holistic approach presented from two perspectives. In one, the inter- relations among major economic activities (1. e., production, consumption, savings, imports, exports and employment) are examined in light of the transactions that they generated among the agricultural, industrial and service sectors of the economy. Data were analyzed in accordance with general theories and by comparison with the experience of other countries. The second perspective uses input-outputanalysis for a more detailed examination of the structural trans- formation. The structures of the economy of Puerto Rico for 1963 and 1972, represented by 44-order input-output matrices, are compared to determine changes in the degree of integration, labor requirements, productivity, import dependence and export dependence. The input—output frame— work is also used in a counterfactual analysis in which hypothetical situations are simulated to distinguish changes in output, employment, imports and exports explained by changes in final demand, both domestic and external, from those due to changes in the structure of production. It was found that the Puerto Rican economy has been transformed as may be expected in a successful economic Samuel Torres Roman development effort, shifting its dual condition into a well-integrated, modern, industrial economy. An adapt- ability for applying innovations and responding to chang- ing economic conditions has been developed. Economic growth in Puerto Rico, however, is not self-sustaining. The economy is vulnerable directly and indirectly to external economic conditions and depends on external trade and capital to continue its growing momentum. This dependence, however, is understandable since the small size of the island makes an outward orientation necessary to maximize the advantages of access to a large United States market. Evident in the analysis is an increased domestic integration implying positive steps toward Self-"reinforcing growth and growing internal demand for intermediate input which stimulates domestic production. This increased domestic integration resulted in considerable substitution of intermediate input for imports, which has lessened external dependence somewhat. Labor absorption in the expanding industrial sectors has been only moderate due to rapid productivity gains. The service sectors have been prominent in absorbing the grow— ing and shifting labor force. This will continue to be crucial as significantly greater labor absorption in industry cannot be expected. Thus, it is essential to Samuel Torres Roman design policies which treat the service sectors as impor— tant elements in economic development strategy. Revital- ization of agriculture could also provide an important source of increased employment. The major portion of the changes in output, employ- ment and trade in Puerto Rico were due to change in final demand which is mainly determined by external forces. Economic fluctuations also come in large part from out— side the island. The influence of structural change has, nevertheless, been substantial. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS A number of people helped me in various ways to accomplish this study. My principal debt is to W. Paul Strassmann who encouraged me to finish the dissertation and, as committee chairman, guided me during the study. My gratitude also goes to Anthony K00 and Victor Smith, for their generous assistance as members ofthe thesis committee. I also wish to express my appreciation to Angel L. Ruiz, Associate Professor, the University of Puerto Rico, who allowed me to use the input-output table he adjusted for his research and for the orientation he provided in technical aspects of the input—output analysis Finally, my sincere gratitude is expressed to my family for their continuous encouragement and moral support. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . Chapter I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . The Problem . . . . . . . Objectives of the Study . The Outline of the Study . II. RELEVANT THEORIES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH Balance vs. Unbalanced Growth . . . Growth in Dual Economies . Growth in Open Dual Economie Stages of Growth . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . III. METHODOLOGY, NOTATION AND DATA Introduction . . . . . . . The Aggregative View . . . The Disaggregative View . The Input- Output Technique Structural Change . . The Input-Output Model . S O I O and Applications of the Input-Output MOdel O O O O O O 0 Limitations of the Input- Output Analysis . . . . . . . Sources of Data . . . . . ' Macroeconomic Data . . . The Input-Output Data . IV. STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION IN P RICO: AN OVERALL VIEW . . . A Brief Historical Review of Rico's Development Strateg, iii UERTO Puerto v C O O Page vi U11>N 11 15 23 36 43 43 44 47 48 51 55 61' 64 64 66 7O 7O Chapter St The Period Before 1947 . . . . . . The New Strategy After 1974: "Operation Bootstrap" . . . . . . Revision of "Operation Bootstrap" Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . ructural Transformation: A General View . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Economic Growth Achieved . . . Change in the Change in the Change in the Structure of Foreign \_Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . Structure of Production Structure of Employment V. STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION: Change in the Process and in the Sources of Financing . . . . . . . . . . Structural Transformation: with Other Countries . . . . . . The Structure of Demand . . . . The Structure of Trade . . . . The Structure of Production . . The Accumulation Process . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . VIE»! I I I O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 VI. Capital Accumulation A DETAILED Comparison Change in the Structure of Production from Input-Output Viewpoint . . . Change in Interdependence and Integration . . . . . . . . . . Import Leakages and Import Substitution . . . . . . . . . Change in Employment an Labor Productivity . . . . . . . . . The economic effects of Change in Demand and Change in Structure . Output Changes . . . . . . . . . Employment Changes . . . . . . . Trade Effects . . . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . Conclusions, Recommendations and Suggestions for Further Research APPENDIX A O C O O O O O O C 0 O O O O O 0 iv Page 71 79 83 85 86 87 93 107 115 126 139 142 146 148 153 155 159 160 160 179 192 210 211 217 221 230 235 235 249 261 Chapter Page Definitions of Variables and the Source of Data for the Regression Equations I I O O O O O O O O O O O . 269 261 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF TABLES Page The Input-output FlOWS o o o o o o o o 0 51 Relative Importancecfi Major Puerto Rican Exports, Years of 1895, 1901, 1940 (In million dollars) . . . . . . . 74 Net Income by Industrial Origin, Puerto Rico, 1940 . . . . . . . . . . 76 Some Selected Indicators of Growth, Fiscal Years 1940, 1947, 1955, 1963, 1972 and 1977 (In per capita constant dollars, 1954 = 100) . . . . . . . . 88 Rate of Growth of Some Economic Indicators of Growth for Some Selected Periods (In percentages) . . . 89 Some Indicators of Economic Growth and Industrialization for Puerto Rico, Jamaica, Dominican Republic and Haiti, Year 1972 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92 Domestic Income of Puerto Rico, Percentage Distribution per Industrial Origin and Total for The Year, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (In percentages and million of dollars) . . 94 Employed Persons in Puerto Rico, Percentage Distribution per Industrial Origin and Total for the Year, Fiscal Years 1940, 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (Percentages and thousand of workers) . 108 Employment Status of Persons 14 years of Age or More, Labor Force Participation Rate and Unemployment Rate, Fiscal Years 1940, 1947, 1955, 1963, 1972 and 1977 (In thousand of workers and percentages) . . . . . . . 113 vi Table 4.15 Page Value of Exports, Imports and Trade Balance and as Percentage of the Respective Gross National Products, Fiscal Years 1940, 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (Value in million of dollars, 1954 = 100) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 Imports, Exports and Trade Coefficients for Some Selected Small Industry Oriented Countries, Year 1972 . . . . . . 119 Traditional and Selected New Products Merchandise Exports, Total Values and Percentages of Total, Fiscal Years 1950, 1963 and 1972 (Values in million of dollars) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122 Merchandise Imports Classified by Consumption, Capital and Intermediate 'Goods, Total Value and Percentages of the Total, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963, and 1972 (In million of dollars and percentages) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 Gross Fixed Domestic Investment in Puerto Rico, in Total Value and Percentages of Total, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (In million of constant dollars, 1954 = 100, and percentages) . . 128 Average Annual Rates of Growth of Construction, Machinery and Equipment and Total Gross Fixed Investment for Some Selected Periods (In percentages). . 129 Sources of Capital Funds in Total Value and as Percentage of Total, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 . . . . . 131 Trade Balance, Unilateral Transfers and Capital Movements to and from Puerto Rico, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (In million of dollars) . . . . . . 133 vii Page Gross National Product, Gross Domestic Product and Factor Payments from and to the Rest of the World, Fiscal Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (In million of dollars) . . . . . . . . . . . 135 Normal and Actual Values of Variables Explaining Accumulation and Resource Allocation Processes, Years 1947, 1955, 1963 and 1972 (As percentage of GDP or corresponding aggregate) . . . . . . . . 143 Sectoral Value Added as a Share of Total Value Added, 44 Sectors, Years of 1963 and 1972 (In percentages) . . . . . . . . 165 Domestic Production Total Linkage Index and Index of Dispersion, 44 Sectors, Years 1963 and 1972 . . . . . . . . . . 170 Direct plus Indirect Intermediate Imported Inputs per Dollar of Output Delivered to Final Demand, Years 1963 and 1972 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183 Alsolute Change from 1963 to 1972 in Direct Domestic Intermediate Input Coefficients and in Direct Imported Input Coefficients, 44 Sectors(Dollars per dollar of output) . . . . . . . . . 188 Average Hourly Earnings for Some Selected Manufacturing Industrial Sectors and Average Annual Rate of Growth, 1954, 1963 and 1972 (Earnings in dollars and change in percentages) . . . . . . . . . 194 Relative Changes from 1963 to 1972 in Direct Domestic Intermediate Input Coefficients, in Direct Imported Intermediate Coefficients and Direct Labor Coefficients, 44 Sectors (In percentages) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 201 viii Table 5.12 Direct plus Indirect Labor per Million Dollars of Final Demand, 44 Sectors, Years 1963 and 1972 . . . . . . . . . . Change in Output, from 1963 to 1972, Due to Change in Demand and Change in the Structure of Production, 44 Sectors (In million of dollars) . . . . . . . . Change in Output, from 1963 to 1972, Due to Change in Demand and Change in the Structure of Production, as Percentage of the Total Change of the Sector and as Percentage of the Source of Change, Five Groups of Sectors . . . . . . . . Change in Employment, from 1963 to 1972, Due to Change in Demand and Change in the Structure of Production, 44 Sectors (Thousands of workers) . . . . . . . . . Change in Output Attributable to Exports, from 1963 to 1972, Due to Change in Demand and Change in the Structure of Production, 44 Sectors (In million of dollars) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Total Output and Output Attributable to Exports, Difference and Ratio, Years 1963 and 1972, Six Groups of Sectors (In million of dollars and decimals) . . Change in Intermediate Imported Inputs, from 1963 to 1972, Due to Change in Demand and Change in the Structure of Production, 44 Sectors (In million of dollars) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Direct plus Indirect Intermediate Immnted Inputs as a Ratio of Total Output, Six Groups of Sectors . . . . . . . . . . . Regression Equations of Processes and Variables Explaining Structural Transformation ix Page 205 213 214 219 223 225 229 232 268 LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 5.1 Sums of Direct Intermediate Input Coefficients from all Sectors for 1963 and 1972, Primary, Manufacturing and Service Sectors (Dollars per dollar of total output) . . . . . . . . 166 5.2 Sums of Intermediate Direct Sales Coefficients to all Sectors for 1963 and 1972, Manufacturing Sectors (Dollar per dollar of total output) . . . 176 5.3 Sums of Direct Intermediate Imported Input Coefficients from all Industries, Primary, Manufacturing and Service Sectors (Dollars per dollar of total output) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182 5.4 Sums of Direct Labor Coefficients for 1963 and 1972, Primary Products, Manufacturing and Service Sectors (Workers per thousand of dollars of output) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 197 5.5 Changes in Direct and Total Labor Coefficient Ratios 1972/1963, Primary, Manufacturing and Service Sectors . . . . 206 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The purpose of this research is to study the struc- tural transformation of the economy of Puerto Rico and to investigate howstructuralchanges have affected the cap- acity of the economy to create output and generate employ- ment 0 Puerto Rico has been transfimmed from a dual colon- ial agricultural economy in 1940 into a modern industrial economy. This transformation was achieved with the helpof 'Operation Bootstrap', a government program designed to attract private business investment by various incentives such as tax exemptions, low plant rental, low interestloans, training of labor, and others. The intent of the program was to elevate both income and employment by attracting labor-intensive plants that could use the abundant andcheap labor available in Puerto Rico.. It was expected that the income of the newly employed workers would be translated into increased demand for consumer goods and a rise in the domestic multiplier engendered by local production of an increased share of intermediate input. A rise in employ- ment in existing local indUstries and newly created indus- tries was also expected, induced by increased demand for consumer and intermediate goods. This chain of events was expected to eventually bring the island economy into a cycle of self-sustained growth. Puerto Rico's growth in the post World War II period was remarkable. The average ratecflfgrowth in real gross national product from 1947 to 1972 was 7.1 percent this year. Other indicators of economic growth were equally impressive. The Problem In spite of the rapid economic growth, the rate of unemployment in Puerto Rico never fell below 11.0 percent in the best years, even though huge annual migration to the United States took pressure off the local job market. Unemployment has been increasing in the Nineteen Seventies, reaching a level of 20.0 percent in 1977, although partici- pation in the labor force fell to 42.0 percent. Further- more, the average annual rate of growth in real gross national product for the 1970-1977 period dropped to al- most zero. Some people, particularly government leaders, attri- bute the economic slow-down in Puerto Rico to the economy's vulnerability to the recession in the United Stateseconomy during the first half of the decade. The vulnerabilityof the export-oriented island economy to United States business recessions was demonstrated by the recession that came with the end of the Korean War, when the promotion of new fac- tories was substantially reduced. In addition, export firms established on the island reacted to reduced demand by clos— ing their entire Puerto Rican establishments. An alternative explanation of the stagnation holds that structural changes in the economy of Puerto Rico have been hindering its growth, limiting the capacity for both output and employment. The potential for such self-defeat- ing changes was suspected as early as the mid Nineteen Seventies when the emphasis of the industrialization program shifted to more capital intensive industries capable of pay- ing higher wages and supplying a larger share of the inter- mediate inputs needed on the island. It was realized then that fast wage increases had reduced the competiveness of labor intensive manufacturing. Additionally, it wascharged that existing industrial activity was poorly linked to the rest of the domestic economy so that its feedback effects were weak. An extreme position of this structuralist view of the stagnation attributes the economic ills of the country to a complete failure of the economic development program. It is argued that Puerto Rico's economy is an example of growth without development, to the point that itis incapable of maintaining growth on its own and of reducing the per- sistent unemployment to acceptable levels. Objectives of the Study The main objective of the study is to investigate the relative importance of these possible causes of the slow- down of the Puerto Rican economy. Special attention is given to structural transformation. One crucial aspect of struc- tural tranmhmmation that is closely explored is its employ- ment implications. In this connection, the research explores the extent to which the changes in output, employment and trade can be attributed to changes in the structures of pro- duction as opposed to changes in domestic and external final demand. It is hypothesized that changes in demand, particu- larly those of external origin, explain a large part of the changes in output and employment. The examination of structural changes will determine the extent to which Puerto Rico has experienced full economic development. The hypothesis for this part of the analysis is that Puerto Rico has undergone structural change that makes the economy capable of more self-sustained growth than has been actually realized. Special attention is given to the way actual struc- tural changes compare with those that can be expectedaccorde ing to theory and the experiences of other countries which have gone through the process of economic development. It is hypothesized that Puerto Rico has closely followed the path of other countries with similar characteristics ofsur- plus labor and small open economies. One crucial aspect requiring careful exploration is the degree of domestic integration in the Puerto Ricanecon- omy and the output and employment implications of structual changes affecting integration. This exploration will permit testing of the extent to which attempts to improve the local lhmages in the domestic economy, emphasized in the last re- vision of the development program, have been successful. The Outline of the Study In Chapter II several theories of economic development are discussed, with special emphasis on those relevant to this study. Theories presented in this chapter provide the framework for evaluating growth in the economy of Puerto Rico. The methodology, notation and sources of data for the study are discussed in the third chapter. An input-output _model, which is the main tool of analysis, is presented. Chapter IV and Chapter V contain the analysis. In the fourth chapter, macroeconomic data from the economy of Puerto Rico for thetnriod 1940 to 1972 are analyzed from the perspective of the theories presented in Chapter II. The growth path of the Puerto Rican economy from 1947 to 1972 is compared to a normal path drawn from a cross-sectional analysis of 101 countries made by Hollis Chenery and Moises Syrquin in 1975.1 In Chapter V a more disaggregated view of the economy for 1963 and 1972 is presented using input-output analysis. The structural transformation, analyzed in the previous chapter from a macroeconomic perspective, is further examined with a more detailed general equilibrium type of analysis. Economic integration and its output and employment implications are examined from this perspective. How much changes in Output, employment and trade can be attributed to structural changes is also discussed. Finally, in the last chapter, the findings of the study are summarized, the conclusions are presented, and some recommendations are made. Here, the final question of the extent to which Puerto Rico has made economic development self-sustaining is explored. 1Hollis Chenery and Moises Syrquin, Patterns of Devel- opment 1950-1970 (Londmn Oxford University Press, 1975). CHAPTER II RELEVANT THEORIES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH The purpose of this chapter is to present a brief sum- mary of theories of economic development which deal with the problem of how to begin and maintain economic growth in underdeveloped countries. Emphasis is placed on those theories that discuss characteristics important in the economy of Puerto Rico. The theories will provide a framework for evaluating the structural changes in this economy during economic growth. Until the Nineteen Forties, theories of economic growth concerned developed economies and placed emphasis on the dy- namics of growth. Existing models stressed the importance of capital / output ratio; study of the multiplier asaameans of evaluating new investments; measures to control the sav- ings ratio, and hence consumption; and placed emphasis on continuing growth.1 However, they had nothing to say about starting growth in an underdeveloped country seeking to in- itiate growth mainly from its own resources. Economists _ 1For comprehensive coverage of these growth theories, together with a very good introduction by the editor, see A. Sen, Growth Economics: Selected Readings (Harmondsworth; Penguin, 1970). turned their attention to these questions in the post-war period, stimulated by pressures coming from many underdevel- oped countries seeking growth. Balanced vs. Unbalanced Growth The basic problem of underdeveloped economies was how to overcome the self-perpetuating circle of low production, small market, small savings, little capital, low production, and so on. Economists agreed about thaneed for increased investment, but differed about how to spread the investments across the economy. Some, like Ragnar Nurkse,2 were in favor of a "bal- anced growth" approach, spreading investment across a wide field of economic sectors and industries, thus enlarging the size and volume of the market. Nurkse emphasized the prob- lem of generating savings. In this connection, he stressed the role of the state in controlling trade movements and en- forcing savings through taxation. Nurkse's version of bal- anced growth placed emphasis on complementarities between different industries in the demand of goods. He claimed that one industry started in isolation may face insufficiency of real demand. Its product may not be absorbeddomesti- cally since those who earn factor incomes in the single in- dustry will hardly spend their entire incomes on theproduct 2Ragnar Nurkse, Problem of Capital Formation in Under- developed Countries and Patters of Trade and Development (New York: Oxford University Press, 1953). of that single isolated industry. Adequate real demand will be forthcoming, he argued, only if sufficiently large numbers of industries are established at the same time, so that they will provide markets for each other. Another approach to the balanced growth hypothesis is that of P. N. Rosestein-Rodan.3 He proposed a "big push" method of transformation, basing his argument on complemen- tarities and external economies in the supply of goods. His prescription was to invest simultaneously on a large number of fronts making it more profitable by capturing external- ities which exist horizontally between industries at thesame stage of production and vertically between different stages of production. Another exponent of the balanced growth paradigm is W. A. Lewis.4 He distinguishes between three sectors:manu- facturing for the home market, agricultural production for the home market and exports. According to his conception, given the rate of growth of exports, manufacturing and agri- cultural production must expand at rates corresponding, but not identical, to their respective income-elasticities of demand. If agricultural production does not grow at anappro- priate rate either the internal commodity term of trade 3P. N. Rosestein—Rodan, "Notes on the Theory of the 'Big Push'", in Readings in Economic Development, edited by Morgan, Betz and Choudry (California, 1963). 4W. Arthur Lewis, Theory of Economic Growth (London: Allen and Unwin, 1955). 10 between agriculture and manufacturing will move in favor of agriculture, thus checkingtfluaexpansion of the manufacturing sector, or the balance of payments will deteriorate due to increase in the demand for food imports. Like Nurkse, Lewis doubted that savings could be generated by the subsistence sector and argued that one has to look to the capitalist be- cause those who receive more will save more. Albert Hirshman5 dissented with the balanced growth view of Nurkse and advocated an opposing strategy of "unbal- anced growth." He argued for development through a "chain of disequilibria", a theory that the expansion of industry A will create external economies for industry B whenever the two industries are in a complementary relationship of any kind. Investment in a key industry will generate outputelse- where with something like a multiplier effect operating through "backward and forward linkages"6 between parts of the economy. This argument also had a spatial dimension. Development takes place through a"master industry" having a specific location. New plants will locate close to the master industry and a "growing point" will be established. Accor- dingLy,growth is necessarily unbalanced geOgraphically. 5Albert 0. Hirshman, The Strategy of Economic Develop- ‘ment (New Haven; Yale University Press, 1958). 6The backward and forward linkages concept will be dis- cussed in Chapter III. 11 Growth in Dual Economies A group of economists examining developing countries has postulated that these economies are divided in two sectors which are so different structurally and behaviorally that they deal with one another almost as though they form two different societies and economies. This observation has been captured in growth models which dichotomize the economies in these sectors; one advanced modern sector is assumed to be capital-intensive and mainly industrial, and a backward sec- tor is characterized as labor-intensive and overwhelmingly agricultural. The first statement of such economic dualism is that of W. A. Lewis7. His formulation deals with two co-existent sectors and the conditions governing the supply of labor fromtfluaagricultural into the growing industrial sector. He argues that a large volume of labor can be transferred into the industrial sector without loss of agricultural output, assuming that there are excessive workers, and hence dis- guised unemployment, in the agricultural sector. Underthis condition of surplus labor in the agricultural sector, the wage rate required to attract labor into the industrial sector need be only slightly above the productivity per unit of labor in the agricultural sector. Workers will be avail- able to the industrial sector at that wage as long as surplus 7W. Arthur Lewis, "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor" Manchester School of Economics and Social Sciences 22 (1954): 139-191. 12 labor exists. All the surplus product above the wages of labor accrues to the industrial class and will promote ex- pansion there. Such a favorable situation for industrial expansion is ended when so much labor is drawn from the agricultural sector that a shortage of workers develops there; or, if the expansion of production in the agricultural sector is so con- strained that shortages of food develop, and the real wage of labor rises due to changes favorable to agriculture in the term of trade between the two sectors. Under these cir- cumstances there will be an increase in the real wages of labor intheuagricultural sector and so the minimum wage necessary to attract labor out of the sector will have to rise. The dual-economy model was modified by a theory of "factor-proportions dualism" proposed by R. S.Eckaus8. In this model the modern sector is capital intensive and factor proportions there are relatively fixed, so that an increase in employment can only be generated by a rigidly propor- tionate increase in capital investment. In the traditional sector, on the other hand, technical co-efficients are var- iable, meaning that a wide range of techniques and factor combinations could be used to yield the same output. An in- crease in available labor given the limited absorptive 8R. S. Eckaus, "The Factor Proportions Problem in Underdeveloped Areas", American Economic Review 45 (1955): 539-65. 13 capacity of the modern industrial sector, will be channelled into the traditional sector and absorbed there by the use of more labor intensiwamethods. There is, thus, no incen- tive for capitalization in the agricultural sector, and the gap in productivity per unit of labor in the two sectors widens as the economy grows. Characterizing models of economic dualism as models for economic growth was emphasized in the Nineteen Sixties. The main thrust of the new models was the inter-relating and consequent transformation of the two sectors so that the vicious circle of underdevelopment is broken and the economy achieves self-sustained growth.9 One of the outstanding models of this approach is one J. C. H. Fei and G. Ranis10 postulated in 1964. Like Lewis, Fei and Ranis assumed a labor surplus in the agricultural sector that can, in the 9This widely used concept was originated in W. W. Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960). Rostow argues that all societies in the world can be located at some point along a continuum marked by five stages: "traditional society," "pre-conditions for take-off," "the take-off to self-sustained growth," "the drive to maturity" and the "age of high mass con- sumption." In his wafit he tries to identify, using historical analysis, the conditions under which transformation takes place to bring a society into a more or less automatic growth cycle which is what self-sustained growth is all about. 10John C. H. Fei and Gustav Ranis, Development of the Labor Surplus Economy, (Homewood: R.D. Irwin, Inc., 1964). This model is summarized critically in B. Higgins, Economic Development: Principles, Problems, and Policies, rev. ed. (New York: Norton Press, 1968). 14 first stage, be drawn on without negative effects in agricul- tural production and, hence, at a constant real wage. Beyond this stage, however, they explored not only the labor inter- relationship of the two sectors, but also the consumption of foods produced in each sector by the members of the other. Additionally, investment by landlords, who have holdings in both sectors, acts as stimulus for the growth of the indus- trial sector. Variable, rather than fixed, factors propor- tions were assumed in the industrial sector. Hence, growth may be supplied by accumulation of either capital or labor, or both. All technical innovation was assumed to take place in the industrial sector. In this model, "developmentll" requires a shift of savings at a rapid rate from the agricultural to the indus- trial sector. The growing industrial labor force depends on the food coming from the agricultural sector. Hence, tech— nical progress in agriculture determines the rate at which labor can be released from the agricultural sector and ab- sorbed into the industrial sector. As Fei and Ranis express it, "When the economy tries to push forward its industrialization effort in the open economy neglecting its agricultural sector, it runs the risk of having the growth process come to 11The emphasis in this model is on economic develop- ment which comes when the structure of the economy is trans- formed so that economic growth is self-sustained. E: 15 a complete halt. Under the pressures of population growth, food shortages caused by stagnant subsistence sector become so over- whelming that the country has to import food at an increasing rate, thus depriving the industrial sector of the needed foreign exchange to import capital goods . . . . In the close economy case, a forced draft industrialization effort in the face of agricultural stagnation will ultimately come to a halt. This results from the diminution of the economy's invest- ment fund due to the disappearance of the agricultural surplus and from the tendency of wage inflation caused by thedeterioration of the terms of trade of the industrial sector D. W. Jorgenson13 varied somewhat the assumptions of this model, explaining economic dualism with emphasis on economic growth. He assumed that the marginal productivity of labor in agriculture is always positive, so that labor is never available to the industrial sector at a constant real wage. Therefore, transfers of labor from the agricul- tural to the industrial sector cause losses of agricultural output. The real wage thus rises continuously through the process of growth and different development paths may emerge. Growth in Open Dual Economies The models explaining economic dualism reviewed so far have assumed a closed economy, thus, neglecting for- eign trade and international capital movements as agents of 12Fei and Ranis, p. 305. 13 Economy," Economic Journal 71 (1961): 309-304. D. W. Jorgenson, "The Development of a Dual 16 growth. From the 1960's surge of decolonization a consider- able number of countries emerged, clamoring for growth and characterised by underdeveloped economies largely dependent on foreign trade. This fact, together with the widespread opinion that a shortage of foreign exchange constituted a major developmental bottleneck, underlined the need to bring an "open-economy" assumption into the growth models explain- ing dualism. Fei and Ranis realized the need to bring foreign trade into their model and discussed this possibility in one chap- ter of their booklA. According to them, a development oriented economy benefitted from foreign trade in four ways. First, and most important, the export sector, together with the foreign sector, constitutes a "powerful new production function available to the economy" through which the input required to produce the food and industrial consumer goods needed by the workers in the export sector are converted into exportable goods which can be exchanged for imported capital and raw material needed for the expansion of the industrial sector. This, in their opinion, gave access to a foreign production function more efficient than any alternative dom- estically available. Secondly, and related to this, a whole range of technological alternatives assembled abroad be- comes available, from which the country can pick those best 14Fei and Ranis, Chapter 8. l7 suited to its resource endowment and development strategy. Thirdly, the foreign sector can be viewed as an important additional source of savings to finance expansion of the domestic industrial sector. Last, and less conspicuous, the export provides, in itself, an additional source of savings available for the expansion of the domestic industrial sector. Fei and Ranis, however, saw foreign trade, not as an engine of growth, but just a facilitator of it. After bring- ing trade into their model they concluded that: "The basic structural characteristics which dominate the preponderant domestic subsis- tence sector in the closed economy must continue to receive the planner's prime atten— tion in the open economy. In other words,what we believe to be the heart of the matter, the expansion of the agricultural productivity to fuel the development process via a consistent and balanced pattern of resource allocation within the dualistic economy, is still at the center stage when the economy is open to trade and foreign capital inflow." 5 Pessimistic views about the role of international trade appeared in the under-developed countries long before foreign trade was incorporated into growth models. A dis- tinctive pattern of development thinking began to evolve among economists in Latin America, centered in the U. N.Econ- omic Commission for Latin America (ECLA) under the leadership of R. Prebischl6. The central argument was an attack on E 15Ibid., p. 206. 16ECLA, A Contribution to Economic Integration in Latin America,(New York: United Nations, 1961) andTn R.Prebiséh;, "The Economic Development of Idltin America and its PrinCiple Problemsf'Economic Review of Latin America, 7 (1962): part 1. l8 traiflflcnal theories of international trade in which special- ization is assumed to bring benefits to all participants, to the primary producer as well as the industrial. The analysis was focused in three main directions: first, an analysis of trade relations among countries on the basis of a "centre- periphery" dualism stressing terms of trade imbalance that worked in favor of the industrial countries; second, a strong emphasis on industrialization with the objective of correcting the imbalance; and third, a concentration on the social and structural problems of underdevelopment. Deterioration in the terms of trade, the negative consequences of import-substitution industrialization which increased dependence on intermediate and capital goods, the inroads of transnational companies and conglomerates (TRANCO) and the growing volume of debt repayment and repatriated profits which exceeded capital inflows and aid, led to a growing emphasis on viewing the Latin American economies as "dependent" rather than "peripheral." One of the first to lay the foundations of "dependency economics" was the Brazilian, Celso Furtado.17 He was init- ially a revisionist, strongly in favor of industrialization l7Celso Furtado, "Capital Formation and Economic Development" in The Economics of Underdevelopment. A. Agar— wala and S. P. Singh, eds., (New York: Oxford University Press, 1963) and C. Furtado, Development and Underdevelopment (Berkeley:University of California Press, 1964). 35 wit 9111' em to the th. fi: ca na it ti all du th of 19 as a way to overcome the term of trade imbalance. Disenchanted with this approach, he presented a theory of underdevelopment which relied on the manner in which the capitalist system achieved only partial penetration in the underdeveloped econ- omies, resulting in a disequiliberated dependent economy yet to be transformed. Furtado argued that in the underdeveloped countries the industrial sector developed in a condition of permanent competition with imports, and the technologies adopted in- hibited faster transformation of the economic structurethrough the absorption of the subsistence sector. At the same time there was continued reliance on primary exports in order to finance the risingauuiincreasingly essential import bill for capital goods, intermediate goods for established industries and imported produce for urban markets. Thus, neither exter- nal dependence nor dependence on primary exports have in real- ity been reduced by industrialization. An essential assump- tion in this view is that the industrial employment was small and low waged and that the high profits obtained by the in- dustrialist remained in the hands of the ruling oligarchy so that the feed-back effects to the rest of the economy were small. Moreover, most of the industrial activity was geared to the substitution of goomspreviously imported so thatwhen import substitution exhausted its possibilities, the growth of the industrial sector was drastically reduced. in 53' eff Yr ......\r\ 20 A new wave of thinking in dependency economics surged in the Caribbean in the 1960's, influenced in its early stages by the work of the English economist Dudley Seers18 on the effects of large scale business on small, open economies.The main preoccupation in this new thinking was the small sized national economy, which was natural in the Caribbean region. A thorough analysis of the policy options open to small countries seeking development by W. G. Demas19 was the first major theoretical statement. He saw structural trans- formation as the essential ingredient of self-sustained econ- omic growth. In regard to structural transformation he wrote: I include seven basic elements in the term "transformation of the structure of produc- tion." These are the capacity to transform as determined by political and social processes and attitudes; the unification of the national markets for goods and services; the shift of production and of labor as between primary, secondary and tertiary sectors of the economy; the development of an increasing degree of inter- dependence among domestic industries and activ- ities; changes in the importance and composi- tion of foreign trade; the reduction of dualism in the economgé and the development of appropriate institutions. 18Dudley Seers, "Big Companies and Small Countries: A Practical Proposal," Kiklos 16 (1963): 599-608. 19William G. Demas, The Economics of Development in Small Countries, with Special Reference to the Caribbean, (Montreal: McGill University Press, 1965), 20 Ibid., p. 8. int mar ZEI‘ 21 Demas saw structural transformation, however, as difficult to achieve in a small economy because of skewed re- source distribution, the need to specialize to take advant- age of economies of scale, the corresponding dependence on international trade, and the small size of the internal market. He advocated integration of the region into a common market system as the most hopeful escape from this trap. The hoped for integration in a common market among the Caribbean countries has proved very hard to achieve because of the dependency of the individual economies on a metropole and TRANCO establishments. Thinking along these lines has lead to a historical approach which emphasizes the institu- tional and structural disadvantages of dependent economies and their continuity through times. This new approach, a shifting away from considerations of size to considerations of structure and historical process, has been proposed by K. Levitt and L. Best21 to bring to- gether a model of export-based growth from Canada and the model of dependency economics. A model of a plantationecon- omy is evolved as a special case of export-based growthunder expansive capitalism. This model is elaborated in stages gen- eralizing experience from the Sixteenth to the Nineteenth Centuries. 21Karl Levitt and Lloyd Best, "Character of the Caribbean Economy" in Caribbean Economy, G. L. Beckford, ed. (Kingston, Jamaica: University of the West Indies, (1975), pp. 34-60. ' plat cul l0 5 are tio he .1; 5L SU ab ch ‘1' ,t Ci NMTW. 22 George L. Beckfordzz, in a wider examination of plantation economies, stressed the importance of the agri- cultural sector. He believes the contribution to income from this sector can be considerable but that the benefits are offset by structural rigidities which hinder transforma- tion and induce a "dynamic process of underdevelopment." He views the contemporary scene in a typical Caribbean economy as consisting of two broad segments: the "overseas" and "residentiary." The overseas component comprises all sectors in which domestic resources are dominated by foreign owned capital. The residentiary component contains those sectors in which residents own and control basic resources. He argues that the bulk of the region's population derives their liveli- hood from residentiary activities while the bulk of the domes- tic resources are concentrated in the overseas component. Thus, income accruing to residents remains low while large surpluses from the exploitation of domestic resources accrue abroad. Furthermore, he points out that "the self-sufficient character of the producing units in the overseas component of the economy stifles the development of internal linkages within the Caribbean economy so that, over time, development of the overseas component generates very limited spreadeffects 22George L. Beckford, Persistent Poverty: Underdevelop- ment in Plantation Economies of the Third World (London: Oxford University Press, 1972). 23 to the residentiary component."23 Thus, he claims, linkages and spread effects are lost because linkages and their multi- plier effects jump toward metropolitan economies. Beckford's view is not necessarily an attack on the principle of foreign investment and its right to an accept- able return. His quarrel is with the overwhelming control of domestic natural resources by foreign interests, control ac- quired most of the time under very advantageous conditions, and their explotation with very small feedback effects on the local economy. This situation is not too uncommon in the Carib— bean, particularly in those countries emerging from colonial plantation economies. Stages of Growth Celso Furtado24 looked into the economies of Latin America and identified three distinct phases in the develop— ment process going on in this area. The pointhe'had in mind while determining these phases was that structural change is inherent in any process of economic development and takes the form of sudden or gradual changes in the demand schedule and and in the composition of supply. According to him, "the 23George L. Beckford, "Caribbean Rural Economy" in Caribbean Economy, G. L. Beckford, ed. (Kingston, Jamaica: West Indies University, 1975), p. 83. 2['Celso Furtado, 'Economic Development of Latin Amer- ica, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970). and n u-.. s.-__ . ‘lb 24 study of development can be regarded as the identification and anticipation of such changes and of the interaction and possible relations between them."25 Initially, Latin America was integrated into the system of international division of labor in which she serves as a supplier of primary products. Exports of these goods constituted the major sources of income and consumer goods were largely provided through imports. Expansion of the world demand for ravmaterialsbrought improvements in the productivity of the export sector. The rise in productivity and consequent increase in the purchas- ing power of the population led to diversification in the pattern of overall demand, and a proportionate rise in the demand for manufactured goods. This process, by facilitating the formation of a domestic market nucleus for manufactured products and the creation of an infrastructure, was the start- ing point for industrialization. This initial phase of industrialization, however, had intrinsic limitations. The industrial activity was limited to the production of non-durable consumer goods-- textiles, leather goods, processed food stuffs and clothing-- which are provided by processing local raw materials or finishing imported semi-manufactured consumer goods. There is little need to assimilate modern technology in an 00C 2b 14:..8 ad in: 760 In W AU P5 1 25 industrial complex geared to the production of consumer goods. Increased industrial output is due largely to the addition of new units of production similar to those already in existence and is dependent on imported equipment and inter- mediate input. There is no question of creating a system of industrial production by steadily diversifying production. Moreover, expansion of industrial output is dependent on the expansion of exports. Thus, stimulus to the industrial sector come from the outside instead of within the local economy. A comment is pertinent about this emphasis cuxmodern technology. This concept has been interpreted by many, un- fortunately some times by policy makers, as meaning the adop- tion of the latest technology. However, the most appropriate meaning is the encouragement of managerial skills and the training of skilled personnel equipped with a thorough know- ledge of technical process so that enough flexibility ismain— tained to incorporate those innovations that may increase productivity. The flexibility to choose the most convenient technology available is very important in a genuine industrial outlook. The world economic crisis of 1929, according toFmrtado, stimulated the emergence of a second phase of industrializa- tion characterized by import substitution. Contraction of the export sector, that came with the economic crisis, led some countries already in the first phase of industrialization ex Cl ’41 '11 26 to expand the industrial sector geared to the home market in an effort to replace, wholly or, in part, goods previously purchased abroad. The 1929 crises, by initially taking the form of a contraction in the capacity to import, provoked exchange depreciations which induced inflationary pressures in almost every country. Both the exchange depreciation and inf lation had the effect of raising the profitability of the industrial nucleus geared to the domestic market. Domestic production improved its competitive position when import Pri ces rose. The existence of unused capacity in the exist- ing industrial sector gave to its supply a certain degree of elasticity needed to increase its output without raising its marginal cost. Moreover, the increased industrial activity Created an additional flow of income which compensated for the loss in income induced by the contraction of exports. Development thus passed from the stage in which it toOk the form of changes in the composition of demand, the fit‘st phase, into a stage in which it could proceed only if the supply structure was transformed. Imports, which had giVEn flexibility to overall supply in the preceding period enabling it to respond promptly to the evolution of the demand SCIledule, are in relative or absolute decline in the second stage and consist increasingly of industrial inputs needed in Producing goods for the domestic market. In fact, as Furtado points out, imports now become the instrument to use in Changing the production infrastructure to serve the home Inarket. tut: 9! C0 27 Although industrialization induced by import substi- tutionin Latin America was principally a response to a crisis of the export sector, Furtado argues that the process could have started sooner in the countries already in the first phase of industrialization, if they have had the benefit of appropriate policies. The importance of appropriate policies, he points out, is underlined by the fact that as import sub- sti tution progressed, industrialization becomes more amd more dep endent on state action designed to concentrate investment on strategic sectors. According to Furtado, the role of government is still more important in a third phase of industrialization, in which state action promoting the establishment of basic in- dUS tries is needed to move the economy to a more complex Stage of industrialization. In this phase the industrial SEC tor expands to supply durable consumer goods for which do‘ulestic production capacity does not exist, and the inter- mediate products needed for the increased production of final conSumer and investment goods. The industrial sector gen- erates, now, part of its own demand and thus the economy be- e ome s more self-sustaining. Furtado did not elaborate on precisely what the go"ernment was expected to do. However, he stated that, "the degree of development depends on the effectiveness of the strategic decision centers. and the flexibility of structures." He fllrther argued that, "what matters is to identify the 28 changes that condition further changes, the agents responsible for the decisions that engender these changes and the elements-- situations or agents-—that offer the greatest resistance to change."26 From this it can be inferred that the state is one of the strategic decision centers and that its role is to keep the structure as flexible as possible by promoting those agents and situations that engender changes favorable to growth and to lessen the resistance of those that hinder this type of change. The government role is, then, that of a facilitator 0f growth and, as such, its participation is more direct or indi rect depending on the relative strength of these opposing forces. Furtado, at that time was very much biased in favor of industrialization. His arguments gave the impression that he believed industrialization was always favorable to gI'O‘Mth. Later on, however, he changed his position on this iSSUe, Another model that deals with stages of growth is that of D. S. Paauw and J. C. Fei.27 They combined insti- tutional, structural and size considerations into a model to eXplain growth and development in an open dualistic econ- omy. Their emphasis was transitional growth from an under- Cleveloped, colonial, primarily agricultural economy, contain- 1 “3 an enclave dedicated to the export of primary exports, \ 26 27 .Ibid, p. 94. omies.DOuglas S. Paauw and John C. H. Fei, The transition on Open Dualistic Econ- Neory and Southeast Asian Experience (New Haven: Yale Univ. Press 1973). .4- r) 5 A.- ‘J .40. (1‘! (‘5) r) (‘J Evy r) n: F! 29 into a new economy operating in an, "epoch of modern growth." The theoretical aspect of the model emphasized a triangular pattern of interaction among agriculture, industry, and the foreign sector and stressing structural changes along the path of growth. The institutional aspects are interpreted as the poli tical and economic-geographic factors which influence government policy and thus shape the course of transitional growth. 5 Given that the background factors inherited from Colonialism are intrinsically heterogenous, Paauw and Fei hYPO thesized that a diversity of actual growth experiences can be found. As they point out, the implication is that real istic developmental theory must be typological in nature. They see the typological approach to development as a prag- mati c compromise along the spectrum between an all-inclusive get'leral theory of universal applicability and individual case by Case studies of each country. In the colonial economy, according to their view, priulzary product exports dominate growth and income is mainly generated by the utilization of land-based resources in the induStrial sector. In modern economic growth, on the other hand. the economic output is primarily created in the indus- t rial sector by human and capital resources. The transition process between these economies thus involves gradual modifica- t ion of a land-based export economy through an industrializa- t ion process requiring significant structural transformations 30 that change the inter-relationships between the agricultural, industrial and foreign sectors. Transitional growth analysis focuses on the process through which these interrelated changes take place as modern growth is gradually initiated. The transition resembles a process of evolution in which two principal sets of changes occur: those having to do with the economy's mode of opera- tion , and those concerning the economy's mode of organiza— tion - Changes in the mode of operation involve a shifting 0f t he importance of major economic variables-~such as pro— dUC—t :lon, consumption, savings, investment, export and import and the role these play in the interactions among key sectors of the economy. The economy's mode of organization refers to the method of social decision making through 'which essential intersectoral functions are carried out. The roles played by alien entrepreneurs, indigenous entrepreneurs, government officials and the significant personnel are an important con— Sid e ration. Although countries emerging from colonialism share many common characteristics, the pattern of transition varies. Val'Zl-éitions appear in the sequence and nature of the transitional Phages. Economic and political backgrounds are important con- Siderations in explaining different growth patterns. The ec . Onomic background concerns economic-geographic factors such 3.3 ll p: 00 31 as the supply of indigenous entrepreneurs, the relative back- wardness of the agricultural sector, the supply of natural resources for primary product exports,and the availability of foreign aid. The political background refers to the society's composition in terms of economic interest groups which con- tend for political power such as remaining aliens, landlords and indigenous entrepreneurs. Paauw and Fei identify three distinctive phases of transitional growth which may be combined into different pat terns of transformation from colonial economy to modern growth. These are: import-substitution growth, export- Promotion growth and export-substitution growth. The emphasis of import—substitution growth is the diversion of primary product export earnings to importation of Producer goods in order to create domestic industrial caI3£icity, enabling production of consumer goods to gradu- ally replace imported goods in the domestic market. Export-promotion growth represents an alternative to 11“va rt-substitution during the initial transition from the colOt‘iial economy. In this growth system the dominate phen- o menon is the expansion of primary product exports. Thus, 11 nder export promotion, the industrial sector's output consists Inainly of productive input required for expansion of primary product exports. In an export-substitution growth phase manufactured 32 goods displace primary products as the dominant exports. The manufactured goods exported are usually labor intensive, sig- naling a shift from land-based to labor—based growth. Thus, exp art-substitution growth with emphasis on labor intensive manufacturing is a phenomenon unique to the labor-surplus type of open dualistic economies and at the center of its analysis is an understanding of how an abundant supply of labor in the traditional agricultural sector is made available to industry. Paauw and Fei viewed successful transitional growth as growth which progressed from colonial epoch to the modern growth epoch, through a combination of these three phases. Col-1n tries with dual open economies and appropriate land endow— ment could progress from export promotion to import substitu- tion to export substitution and, then, modern growth. For Conn tries with open dual economies and a labor surplus, how- err , export-promotion growth was ruled out and transition wc>111d start with import substitution move into export sub- stitution and, then, to the modern growth epoch, if trans- itional growth was successful. They emphasized that for small and Open labor surplus economies, import substitution was a 28 preparatory phase necessary for export substitution to emerge. H. Chenery and M. Syrquin in a recent study also Paauw and Fei, p. 244. -— ' fit...“ 33 focused on the identification of alternative patterns of development.29 The main objective of their study was to pro- ‘vicie a comprehensive description of the structural changes that .ac<:<3mpany the growth of developing countries and to analyze ttleaer interrelationships. Their focus was the major features of? Iresource mobilization and allocation, particularly those asspzeeczts needed to sustain further growth and, therefore, of primary interest to policymakers. They defined a development pattennas a systematic VEII‘j_£1tion in any significant aspect of the economic or social Stzr‘Lxczture associated with a rising level of income or other indices of development. As they put it, In describing the processes of develop- ment we have tried to replace the notion of a dichotomy between less developed and developed countries with the concept of a transition from one state to the other. This transition is defined by a set of structural changes that have almost always accompanied the growth of per capita income in recent decades. The authors selected ten basic processes, defined EDy' trwenty-seven variables, to represent structural character- istics that provided the dependent variables of the statist- 1 C‘il- analysis: investment, government revenue, education, \ ‘v 29Hollis Chenery and Moises Syrquin, Patterns of De— ‘*£ililEEggg£, 1950-1970 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975). 3OIbid, p. 135. 34 domestic demand, production, foreign trade, labor allocation, urbanization, demographic transition, and income distribution. Taken together these ten processes are expected to describe different dimensions of the structural transformation as a poor country develops into a rich one. Available statistics covering the period 1950-1970 for a maximum of 101 countries were analyzed usingregression analysis. Ordinary least squares regressions specified all the structural characteristics as a function of per capita gross national product, population, net resource inflow, and a time trend. The first two independent variables appear in logarithmic form, and squared,to account for non-linearities. Uniform cross-section estimates of the structural transforma- tion were derived and it was found that most of the processes can be described by S-shaped curves, having asymptotes at low and high levels of income. Chenery and Syrquin's analysis leads to identifica- tion of four main patterns of development. The level and orientation of exports and the orientation of production were used as the basic criteria for their typology. A trade orien- tat ion index and a production orientation index were developed, 13‘3st on the deviations of each country's actual values from an eitpected value, derived from the regression equations. With the help of these indexes four principal development strategies were isolated: primary specialization, balanced production a nd trade, import substitution and industrial specialization. 35 Primary specialization corresponds to the established concept of an export-led growth pattern based on favorable primary resources. The study shows that this strategy delays at ructural transformation, but a late acceleration results in a structure similar to all other countries when they reach hi gh levels of per capita income. The authors point out that t h is strategy has its limits since non-oil primary exports are 81‘ owing at very slow rates. Balanced allocation and import-substitution strategies are more ty 13 :ical of large countries. (Population over fifteen million). Imp crt substitution emerged as the least successful strategy and explains low growth rates in many Latin American countries. TWO Latin American countries, Brazil and Mexico, which shifted it on import-substitution into manufacturing exports did achieve high growth rates. Industrial specialization, characterized by above n(>3E‘Tnal trade and an industrial production orientation, has led to relatively high rates of growth for most small countries in this group. The pattern of resource allocation in these coLitatries more closely resembles that of large countries ratliner than other small countries. All countries following thi a pattern have required large amounts of external capital for a period of ten or more years but have been able to reduce dep andence on external capital after the shift to manufactured e RD orts becomes well established. 36 Chenery and Syrquin concluded that the four basic ,paatterns they identified have their counterparts in the (Jeexrelopment plans and policies of the transitional countries air11rm.tinue to expand" and that, "a country's success in devel- C’I> fiL mg non-primary exports is largely a result of government po 1 :icy."33 W This chapter has presented theories of economic de- "e=:1—<:pment designed to resolve the problem of how to initiate 53¢:CD Iaomic growth and maintain it in countries which are signif- 1Czéa-‘Intly underdeveloped. It is pertinent now to re-emphasize t:k;() sse issues that are relevant to an evaluation of growth in 't11‘3 economy of Puerto Rico. Special emphasis has been placed on models of economic 'i‘léi.JLism, that is, those dealing with economies organized in \ 31Chenery and Syrquin, p. 106. 32 37 two parts which are structurally and behaviorally so dif- ferent that they deal with one another almost as though they formed two separate societies and economies. The major thrust has been interrelating and transforming the two sectors so that a self-perpetuating cycle of underdevelopment is broken and the economy can achieve self-sustained growth. A number of models have been presented that deal with growth in a small, open, dual economy which is the situation in Puerto Rico and many of its Caribbean neighbors. Trade ha 3 emerged as a facilitator of growth in that it gives access to foreign production functions that may be more efficient than any domestic alternative available; and, at the same time, makes available a range of technological alternatives from WI": 1 ch the country can pick those best suited to its resources and development strategy. The foreign sector is also an im- PO rtant source of capital to finance expansion of the domes— tic industrial sector. A critical view of export-led growth has also been presented since some authors feel the dependency it generates may hinder self-sustained growth. They express Col"Cern about unequitable distribution, between foreign and domestic interests, of the benefits accruing from this type of growth. A point of crucial importance in the literature is the d ef inition of development as structural transformation that Self- m a”1‘98 an economy capable of self-sustained growth. a “Stained does not, however, mean self-sufficient. 38 Seven basic elements in the structural transformation of the economy have been considered. These elements, which will play a significantrole in the evaluation of economic change in Puerto Rico, are: l. The capacity to trmnfiorm. This is the capacity of an economy to continually apply innovations that can improve social produc- tivity and to adapt promptly to changing con- ditions, such as changes in prices and market situations. The capacity to transform is in- herently linked to basic socio-cultural and political attitudes and practices. The unification of the national market for goods and services. This implies increased transactions for markets rather than mere sub- sistence production. The unification of frag- mented local markets into a national market is essential to capture potential economies of scale, exploit fully the national resources and achieve efficient distribution of goods and services. A shift of production and labor between primary, secondary and tertiary sectors of the economy. This means a continuous process of relocating factors of production in accordance with changes 39 in relative productivity and changes in demand patterns as per capita income rises. This process manifests itself in altering the dis- tribution of the labor force and changing out- put composition from primary to secondary and tertiary activities. The development of an increasing interdepen- dence among domestic industries and activ- ities. This implies forging links in the dom- estic production structure so that industries become more interdependent. The interdepen- dence manifests itself in a network of forward and backward linkages within the production struc- ture so that the products of an increasing num- ber of industries become the input for other industries. This, in turn, implies a rapid growth of domestically produced intermediate and capital goods. Changes in the importance and composition of foreign trade. The transformation of an economy is accompanied by an increase in the absolute volume of foreign trade and a change in the composition of imports away from consumergoods. This islfluenet effect of Opposing tendencies 40 such as an increased need for imported capital and intermediate goods arising from the expansion of industrial activity and in- creased demand for all consumer goods in- cluding imports arising from improvement in real income, on one hand, and the changing composition of demand from goods to services, on the other. The latter is dictated by rela- tive income-elasticities of demand, internal linkages which provide local intermediate input and technological progress which economizes in the use of imported raw materials. The reduction of dualism in the economy.Trans- formation involves some reduction in the dis- parities between return to factors of produc- tion within the national economy, disparities which constitute the essence of dualism. In this connection, it should be pointed out that the existence of a large surplus of labor, either unemployed or in some form of disguised unemploy- ment, may be interpreted as a form of dualism since the marginal product of this labor is too low to have any significance in the economy. The development of appropriate institutions. 41 This includes a complex of supporting insti— tutions that make structural transformation and a high rate of savings and investment pos- sible. Important elements of this complex are tax mechanisms, financial institutions, and the administrative systems that facilitate savings and investment, both public and pri- vate. Another important consideration required in the defin— .a t:jion of economic development is self-sustained growth. Such gyr‘cawth is self-reinforcing and requires sufficient domestic sszafixrings, both public and private, to support a significant [>c3‘xrtion of domestic investment. It also requires generation o;f’ adequate internal demand to continually stimulate growth Wi t hin the local economy, even when foreign demand is an im- Por tant engine of growth. Another important issue in the literature is the I’l’c’F>er role of industrialization in the development process. 'rPIGE industrial sector must be expanded to be capable of pro- vw1<3iitug an increasing supply of domestic consumer and invest- Ineztltl goods to substitute for the traditional primary exports OI) t:he decline in world markets. The expansion of industrial a ct 1vity also absorbs part of the excess labor existent in t flea ‘traditional sector of the dual economy. Moreover, the in c:(Dme it generates creates demand for its own output and 42 for that of the agricultural sector. In this connection, agriculture could be an important source of savings to in- itiate further expansion of the industrial sector and once this is underway, agricultural activity must continue to be vigorous, capable of providing an increasing supply of con- :sumer goods to an expanding and wealthier industrial labor .fcarce. If agriculture fails to grow at a concomitant rate, (emcpansion in the industrial sector and in the whole economy <2c>tJld come to a halt. A final issue relevant to analysis of the Puerto Rti.c:an is the proper role of government in the development p>r‘<3vcess. The state is a key decision center promulgating de- ions vital to the flexibility of the economic structure. czi s; I't £3 proper role is that of a facilitator promoting conditions t11.51 t favor growth and opposing those that would hinderchanges Re C essary for growth. CHAPTER III METHODOLOGY, NOTATION AND DATA Introduction This study is centered on the structural changes that have occurred in the economy of Puerto Rico between 1947 and 19 72, while the economy was going through transition growth. Transition growth, as was explained in the previous chapter, emp hasizes a triangular pattern of interaction among agricul- tur e, industry and the foreign sector. The focus of this anal— ys i s is the interaction that took place between these sectors Whi 1e the Puerto Rican economy was shifting into a more highly developed state. The frame of reference for evaluating this transformation is the set of economic development theories dis- cuSSed in the previous chapter. The method is to be a historical approach. This ap'Pli‘oach is reflected in the very concept of transitional growth as a process of change from an underdeveloped into a more highly developed economy. Growth in this study is pre- 8e IIted from two distinctive viewpoints. One, close to the ma Q1‘<>economic tradition, deals with economic magnitudes con- Si . 8 t etit with an aggregative view of the economy. In the 43 44 closer to the general equilibrium approach, a more 0 ther, in which an input-out- clisaggregative viewpoint is presented, Both perspectives, however, put framework is employed. jfrollow a holistic approach emphasizing intersectoral relation- ships in the economy as a whole and the change in these over I: :ime. The Aggregative View This view conforms to a design which emphasizes macro- onomic relationship; the majoreconomic activities such as e: c: I) I? oduction, consumption, savings, investments, exports, im- r><:> rts and employment are the focus of this perspective of the an alysis. The interrelatedness of these economic activities, the terms of the transactions they generate among the key 1.13L as well as the pattern of change in (:tors of the economy, £342: forms the core of the analysis. tffj;r other elements. The normal growth level for each variable for 1947, :1. 955, 1963 and 1972 is found by substituting in the regres- 53 :ion equations Puerto Rico's per capita income, population, a rd net resource inflow for these years. It is assumed that t: Ine cross-sectional relationships depicted in the regressions 11nc31d intertemporally so that a time pattern for the behavior (3 if these variables can be established. The real value of each variable is compared with the I1(3'I‘mal value for each year. The pattern of deviations is a-1'1£Ellyzed for meaningful trends in terms of the developmental theory presented in Chapter II. \ 2Hollis Chenery and Moises Syrquin, Patterns of Devel- 2—Pm\ent 1950-1970, (London: Oxford University Press, 1975), pp- 16-18; 48-49; 205. 47 The Disaggregative View The methodology proposed in this section takes the It examines the saunalysis discussed above one step further. (1 etailed intrasectoral composition of the major sectors pre- ‘xrhjously analyzed. From this perspective intrasectoral trans- if (armation can be further analyzed. One of the most comprehensive ways of investigating 1: tie interdependence of different sectors of the economy is Leontieff . t: he input-output analysis developed by Wassily W. this technique the economy is broken into small sectors Ilia: 212:1.d the flow of goods and services among the sectors is re- 4 c:<:> Ided to indicate systematically the relations among them dividing the economy into finer units, input-output tech- 13:9? Insz l1omy, 1914-1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1941 and 1951) . “In the input-output terminology "industry" and "sector" are used interchangeably to refer to a small portion of the e(:c’l'lomy. This study adheres to this usage. Each major sector :eferred to in the aggregative analysis will be subdivided in- C) "£irious subsectors (or industries) in the input-output analysis. ' 48 input each industry requires in order to produce a given Linit of its own output. Outflow is the product an industry can sell both to final demand and to other industries to meet their intermediate input requirements. The Input—Output Technique and Structural Change The input-output framework is very convenient for s tudying interindustry structural relationships and their change over time. An imput—output matrix represents the structure 0 f the economy at a given point in time. By comparing the matrices for two different periods inferences about structural c: h anges can be made. The first to use input-output analysis to study S t ructural changes was Wassily Leontieff in a study of the Un :ited States economy. Anne Carter also used this approach in studying the United States economy for technological Ch anges which had affected industrial specialization, as as reflected in he 1: input-output tables for 1939, 1947 and 1958.6 We 11 as direct primary input requirements, These st:I—ldies will supply major methodological roots for the one 1.1:; d ertaken here. \- 5W. W. Leontieff, The Structure of the American Econ— % 1914-1939; also in W. W. Leontieff et al., Studies in t1)\e8tructure of the American Economy (New York: Oxford Univer— Sit), Press, 1953). 6Anne P. Carter, Structural Change in the American W (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970). 49 There are several other studies of the changing in- put-output structure. The bulk of the work in this field concerns countries for whom sequences of comparable input- output tables have been available for some years such as the Netherlands, Norway and Japan7. In general, the em- phasis of these studies of structural change has beenlnainly statistical and methodological in contrast to Carter's study and the one proposed here, which are more factual and concerned with specific developments of the economy and their impact on specific economic variables. The principal study in Puerto Rico which dealt with structural change using input-output was made by Angel L. 28312.8 He made estimates of capital coefficients anddirect zand indirect capital and labor requirements per unit of final demand and output, all defined in input-output termin- <:>logy. Making use of his data which covered the period :EFrom 1954 to 1963, and some mathematical models with an in- lavut-output framework, he shed some light on various con- <:.epts about capital-output ratios and their usefulness for 7Christian B. Tilanus, Igput-Output Experiments: The _£1etherlandsJ 1948-1961 (Rotterdam: Rotterdam University Press, 1-5966); Per Sevaldson, "Changes in Input-Output Coefficients," 1LT! Structural Interdependence and Economic Development, ed. uriilaor Barna (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1963), pp. 303—28; I”1‘3nri Theil, "Applied Economic Forecasting," in Vol. 4, Studies thl JMathematical and Managerial Economics ed. Henri Theil (4(3111cago: Rand McNally Company, 1966). 8Angel L. Ruiz, "Capital Imports and the Economic De- "‘3llopment of Puerto Rico; Studies in Input-Output Framework" (:I?11. D. Dissertation, University of Wales in England, 1976). 50 planning purposes, the labor absorption problem in a labor surplus economy, the capital and labor content of exports and competitive imports and related problems. Al- though Ruiz's interest was mainly methodological, he com- pared two different structures of the economy, one for 1954 and one for 1963, as represented by input-output tables for those two years. He discussed the implications of structural changes in these two periods for the employment structure of the Puerto Rican economy. He found large increases in labor productivity, in almost all sectors of the economy, resulted in a drop in sectoral labor requirements, both direct and indirect. The matrices he compared were based on total domestic plus imported input only. However, to study structural change in an open economy, the domestic Imatrices alone are also needaito enable the researcher to single out local impacts.9 Richard Weisskoff10 examined the same period, also lasing input-output analysis. He looked into movement in janome and employment and the distribution of each in Puerto TFiico between 1954 and 1963. The foundation for this analysis, .1.ike the previous one, is the structural differences in the €3<2onomy as reflected in the gross input-output tables for \ 9See James Riedel, "Factor Proportions, Linkages and t1113 Open Developing Economy," Review of Economics and Sta- t istics 57 (November 1975): 487-94. 10Richard Weisskoff, Colonial Industrialization in the —Sifigibbean: The Economic Development of Puerto Rico, Department (315' Economics, Iowa, 1976, (to be published). 51 the total economy during the two years chosen. He found in- creased industrial interdependence in several sectors dur- ing this period, but observed that the interdependence was weakened by import and export leakages. The Input-Output Model The input-output flows are summarized in Table 3.1. Table 3.l--The Input-Output Model Inputs to Industry J Final Total from 1 2 . . . . n Demands Output 9 a 2 X21 X22 ' ' 'in y2 X2 >‘ O O O I O . ir “ J. U 0 o o o o o 1 {D 1 a O O O O O 0 w I O O O O O 4 C'- J H n an x2 Xnn yn Xn ‘U'alue Added V1 V2 . . .Vn 1? i <>ta1 Inputs X1 X2 . . .Xn % X1 1 i=1 From the table the following notation and definitions can b e set forth: t = output of sector i in year t as input ij in sector j. 52 Xt = gross domestic output flow vector in year t (nxl) t xt ai.==_ij* = direct requirement of the output J Xt of any sector i per unit of output j of any sector j in year t t t . ,A = [ai.] = input coefficient or technical J coefficient matrix of Leontieff system in year t (nxn) Mt = foreign imports vector in year t (lxn) t t mij== Mij = direct requirement of imports from X any sector 1 per unit of output j of sector j in year t t t . Am ==[mi.] = import component of technical J coefficient matrix in year t (nxn) t t t t Ad ==[ai -mi.]-mi.]= domestic component of technical J J J coefficient matrix in year t (nxn) Yt = final demand flow vector in year t (nxl) Yt = import component of final demand m in year t (nxl) Y3 = domestic component of final demand in year t (nxl) Given the above definitions and assuming linearity and h(Dmogeneity of the production functions in the producing sectors, tille balance equations of the input—output models, in matrix r1<3tation, can be stated as: X = AX = (Y - M) (l) 53 meaning that gross domestic output equals intermediate produc- tion plus domestic final demand. Solving for X, equation (1) becomes -1 (Y - M) (2) '1 "l . g . . 11 (1 - A) = (l - aij) , or Leontieff s inverse matrix, gives the total requirement (direct plus indirect) of the output of any sector i per unit of output of sector jdelivered to final demand. The Leontieff inverse ‘makes no distinction between im- portedznuilocally producedinput requirements.However,to measure local impact the latter are the meaningfulones. Th isolate local impact the Leontieff model can be modified as follows: The import vector can be broken down into its inter- mediate and final demand M = A x + Y (3) and the balance equation of the system in matrix notation can be expressed as x = AX + [ Y - (Am x + Ym) ] (4) ‘which solved for X becomes 1 X = (1 — A + Am) (Y - Ym). (5) Since A = A - A and Y = Y - Y , equation (5) can be stated as d m d m X=(1-A)-1Y (6) d d 11The inverse existsif the (l — A) matrix is non-singular 54 *which can also be expressed as d. (7) dij gives the locally produced input requirement of the output of sector 1 per unit of output of sector j and (i - d )-1 gives the direct plus indirect locally 13 produced input requirement per unit of output delivered to final demand. Since d . = a.. - m equation (7) can 13 13 ij’ also be expressed as -1 X = (l - a.. + m .) Y (8) Introducing the following definitions for labor re- quirement NC = (n?) = direct labor requirement coef- J ficient vector in year t (lxn) n? = direct labor requirement per 3 unit of output of sector j in year t Eind, then, pre—multiplying the labor requirement vector of bqt by the domestic inverse matrix (1 - dij)—1, we find the (iirect plus indirect labor requirement per unit of output <>f each sector delivered to final demand, or t t -1 = - o 9 e N (l dij) ( ) In this, e is a row vector (lxn) giving the direct plus in- clirect labor requirement for each sector per unit of output <1elivered to final demand. 55 Domestic final demand Y can be broken down in its com- ponents: c . . Yd = domestic consumption YI = domestic investment d E = exports Yd and, then, the direct plus indirect production of each sector attributable to exports can be obtained by post-multiplying the export vector of final demauiYg by the domestic inverse, (1 _ dij)-l or w = (1 - d )‘1 YE (10) inhere W is a column vector (nxl) which gives the direct plus :indirect production of each industry 1 attributable to ex- Iaorts. jg§pplications of the Input-Output Model The direct and total (direct plus indirect) coeffi- czients of the input-output matrices for 1963 and 1972 are (:0mpared for a first impression of the structural trans— fFormation that occurred in the Puerto Rican economy dur- iung this ten year period. From these comparisons some in- fPerences can be made about changes in the degree of inter- clependence among domestic industries and activities. The total coefficient is used to build a backward 1fiinkage index to measure the degree of integration in the 56 domestic economy.12 The backward linkage of a sector indi- cates the output expansion potential of the attempt to supply, through production in other domestic sectors, the inputneeded in the sector in question. Thus, a high linkage index points to a better integrated sector which may stimulate economic production in other sectors and have a greater multiplier effect on growth. It must be emphasized that the linkage index gives no assurance that this is actually going to happen but it points toward this possibility. This point will be discussed further in a later section. Operationally the backward linkage of sector j, L?’ is (defined as the column sum of the input inverse (Leontieff in- xaerse), modified to consider local impact only;13 or LB = g (1 - d ‘1 (11) 12An analogous forward or output-utilization index which captures the (Output potential of the utilization of the output of one sector as in- puts in the activities of other sectors, is also defined in the litera- ture. However since both indexes look at the same transaction from the viewpoint of a purchasaor a sale, only one is needed in using the index as a measure of economic integration. Hence, the less equivocal back- ‘ward linkage index is used in this analysix. 13The concept of linkage was first introduced by Albert 0. Hirshman in the Strategy of Economic Development (New York: Yale University IPress), 98-119. It has been defined operationally in different ways by several authors. See, for example, Pan A. Yotopoulos and Jeffrey IB. Nugent, "A Balanced Growth Version of the Linkage Hypothesis," jguarterszournal of Economics, 87 (May, 1973): 157-72; Michael lBoucher, "Some Further Results of the Linkage Hypothesis," Quarter- ;ly Journal of Economics, 90 (May, 1976): 313-18; and Leroy P. Jones, "The Measurement of the Hirschmanian Linkages," Quarterly Journal _5;f Economics, 90 (May 1976): 323-33. The Yotopolous and Nugent \7ersion is used here. 57 To complement the linkage index a coefficient of dis- jpersion (Vj) is computed for each sector. This may be de- ;fined as n n % z (21' _-I1-1- Z z”)2 (12) 1-1 3 i=1 13 V. _ J - _ n l ”a z 213' i-l -1 V can be interpreted as an index ‘vvhere Z , = (l - d . 11 11) j sshowing to what extent industry j draws evenly on the system c>f industries-~in the case of a relatively low value of Vj' C)r it may indicate that industry j draws from just a few ssectors in the system of industries--in the case of a large ‘Jj. The higher the linkage index and the lower the index of (flzispersion the better integrated to the rest of the economy £3 sector is, in the sense of having noticeable effects on C>tzher industries, effects which are well spread over the S ystem of industries. The direct and total (direct plus indirect) labor re- ‘§.Llirements are determined for 1963 and 1972 and then compared of em- t1C> examine the production structure from the viewpoint I)3—-<)yment requirements. The total labor requirements are com- I>Llted according to the formula given in equation (9) above. \ Studies in Intersectoral Rela- 4Nooregard P. Rasmussen, ti'~<:>ns (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1956): pp. 140-42. 58 Likewise, direct and total (direct plus indirect) im- ported input coefficients for the two economic structures are computed and compared to examine changes in the struc- ture of production from the viewpoint of import dependence and import leakages. The direct imported input coefficients (mj) represent tlie difference between the direct coefficients computed from true total (domestic plus imports ) matrix and the direct cc3efficients computed from the domestic matrix alone. Simil- arrly the direct plus indirect imported input coefficients(gj) alre the difference between the direct plus indirect input co- eifficients obtained from the total matrix, and the direct P1413 indirect coefficients calculated from the domestic ‘maitrix. In terms of the notation used above n t m =2 (a.. - t> 1 i=1 13 ij (13) and n r -1 r -1 gj =1: (1 - aij) - (1 - dij) (14) All the structural changes mentioned above are ob- taimed from a comparison of the economic structure of 1963 and that of 1972. The results are presented by way of tables and seatt:er diagrams. 59 The input—output framework can be used in a counter- faactual analysis in which hypothetical situations are simul- EitEd to interpret changes in an economy from one period to another.15 The technique is used in this study to anal)’ze tlie output, employment and balance of payment effects which Inaive occurred; and to determine the extent to which these clianges can be attributed to changes in the structure of [>Iroduction and the extent to which they can be traced to clianges in demand. In the first simulation, dealing with output effects, tlie structure of 1963 is combined with the final domestic deemandfor 1972 to generate a hypothetical production for 11972 due only to changes in demand. This hypothetical pro- dllction is then compared to actual productionin.l9fl2andthe dilfference is attributed to changes in the structure of pro- dllction. In terms of the notation and formula defined above tliis output effect can be expressed as: 72 -l 72 63 -1 72 (l - dij ) Y - (1 - dij ) Yd . (15) 15The 'counterfactual' historical analysis is very faShionable among some economics' writers and has been used 3y economics' historians and economic theorists. See for ex- auVPIle, Robert W. Fogel, "The Reunification of Economic History ‘w1-t11 Economic Theory," American Economic Review 55, Supple- Inent (1965): 92-98; John R. Meyer and Alfred H. Conrad, "Econ— onlilz Theory, Statistical Inference and Economic History," $31.11 of Economic History 17 (1957'): 524-53; Allen c. .ley and Jeffrey C. Williamson, Modeling Economic Devel- 0‘3nhent and General Equilibrium Histories," American Economic eView 65, Supplement (1973): 450-58. 60 An analogous simulation may be created to analyze the changes in employment. The 1963 domestic inverse matrix and the 1963 manpower coefficient matrix are used with the 1972 final demand to determine the hypothetical manpower that would have been required if only the demand had changed. The dif- ference between this hypothetical manpower requirement and the actual requirement of each sector is attributed to change in the structure of production. Again, in terms of the nota— tion and formula given above, the employment effect that is attributable to structural change can be written as: 72 72 -1 72 63 63 —l 72 N (l - dij ) d N (l - dij ) Yd . (16) To break down the changes in trade into those attrib- utable to changes in the structure and those attributable to changes in demand, two simulations are needed. In one, the 1963 structure and the export portion of 1972 final demand are combined to find a hypothetical production attributable t° Changes in the export level alone. This hypothetical pro- duct ion is then compared to the real one, that is, the one generated by the 1972 structure and the 1972 export vector, and the difference is the change in production attributable to airport due to changes in the structure of production. In t 81:11:, of the notation used above this export effect is: 72 -1 E72 63 -1 E72 (1 - dij ) Yd - (l - dij ) Yd . (l7) 61 In the other simulation the change in direct plus in- direct imports attributable to alteration in production struc- ture is obtained. The first step is to make a simulation sim- ilar to one above but using an inverse matrix for 1963 and 1972 which includes both domestic and imported inputs. Then, the output effect obtained from the earlier simulation using the domestic inverse alone is deducted from the output effect obtained from this simulation. The difference is the change in direct plus indirect imports attributable to changes in the structure of production. In symbolic terms this importeffect is summarized as: -l 72 63 [(1 - a. ) y - (1 - a -l 72]. (18) Limitations of the Input-Output Analysis While a column of input-output coefficients gives a fairly detailed description of how a particular product or group of products was made, it is a compressed summary of a much greater body of information. No matter how detailed the classification, each product category will represent a mix of products. Thus, some changes in coefficients in the matrices of two difference periods may be due to changes in "product 62 mix" instead of changes in the technology of production. Hence, structural changes inferred from the observation of changes in technological coefficients may be somewhat dis- torted by this possibility. Furthermore, since each product category is an aggre- gate of several parts, its path of change is affected by the pattern of growth of its components. Thus, growth in some components may be neutralized by decline in others, giving a false impression of stability in the sector. A possible way to deal with the problem of aggregation is to disaggregate as much as possible and keep each category as similar as possible within a category from one matrix to another. In the study, the different input-output tables were reconciled to keep them as comparable as possible. However, this provision does not entirely correct the distortion brought about by the aggregation. Difficulties in allowing for qualitative change in a fixed classification framework bring another source of dis- tortion. A fixed classification scheme tells nothing about the changing quality composition of each category. To the extent that "different" cannot be expressed as "more" or "less" it is not measured at all. Hence, a unit of improved product measured in quality units may represent a larger amount of input compared to a unit of older product. To the extent that quality improvements are ignored the input used are underestimated. 63 Another limitation of input-output has to do with the proper use of analysis. Input-output analysis may be an effec- tive tool to diagnose sectors susceptible to policy changes and, thus, may be useful in establishing general guidelines for policy. It does not provide, however, enough information to tell specifically how to deal with these sectors and what specific policy changes may be appropriate. This kind of in- formation may be obtained by applying other types of analysis to the sectors in question. A high value of:Umutflnmputcoefficients, used here as a linkage index, simply indicates a high interdependence among sectors. But, as L. Jones has argued, this interdependence is translated into "linkage" only if it can be made effective in a causal sense, that is, if the intermediate input required by a sector induces other sectors to increase their produc- tion. However, since interdependence is a necessary condi- tion for linkage to exist, high coefficients suggest poten— tial linkages that may be further examined for causality in a case - by - case basis.16 Moreover, input-output analysis is not a substitute for the crucial economic critera of profitability. No matter how large its linkage coefficient, the economic activity is justifiable only if it is profitable, that is, its benefits must be larger than its costs; and optimization criteria 16 L. Jones,"The Measurement of the Hirshmanian Indexes," p. 322. 64 require that those activities in which this difference is largest be favored. However, high linkage indexes may help to detect sectors in which large disparities between social and private benefits and costs may exist. This possibility can be further explored with other tools such as cost-benefit analysis and, if confirmed and the means of financing are available, correctives measuressuch as subsidies,could be considered. Or, a thorough investigation of the production process in an industry singled out by input—output analysis as having high output and employment linkages, may help to determine crucial links that need to be strengthened to make those linkages effective and thus may affect private benefits or costs in other sectors. In conclusion, the role of input-output as a diagnos- tic tool and the need to use it in combination with other toolscfi'analysis must be kept in mind so that the analysis may be put to proper use. Sources of Data Macroeconomic Data The data for the aggregative view come from Puerto Rican national accounts, trade statistics and manpower statis- tics collected and published by the Puerto Rico Planning Board. 65 National accounts have been published in Puerto Rico consistently since 1947, although some estimates previous to 1939 do exist. The conceptual basis for the Puerto Rican Income and Product statistics follows very closely those of the United States Department of Commerce. Gross product is defined, as in many countries, as the value, at market prices, of goods and services produced in theeconomy during the year. The most important charge is the payments to the factors of production, i. e. salaries, profits, rent income and interest payments. These payments are known as net income or alternatively, net product, at factor cost. The major accounts of the system are five: (1) Gross Product and Net Income; (2) Income and Expenditures of Persons; (3) Income and Expenditures of Commonwealth and Munici- pal Governments; (4) Transactions with the Rest of the World; and (5) Savings and Investments. In spite of the fact that because of its association with the United States, Puerto Rico cannot be politically classified as a nation (see Chapter 4 on this), the Puerto Rico Planning Board estimates closely resemble a national concept. In other words, they include the income received from Puerto Rican investments and salaries earned by Puerto Rican seasonal workers abroad. The estimates exclude the 66 income received in Puerto Rico by investors and salaries earned by workers from abroad. In this connection,trans- actions with the United States are considered as transactions with the rest of the world. The manpower statistics are gathered by the Puerto Rico Department of Labor. This information is summarized and published annually by the Planning Board. The external trade statistics are compiled by the bureau of the Census of the United States of the Department of Commerce and sent to the Puerto Rican Planning Board. This information is summarized there and published annually. The macroeconomic data needed for this study were obtained from several issues of three publications of the Puerto Rico Planning Board where the information is col- lected annually. They are: Income and Products of Puerto Rico, the Economic Report to the Governor, and External Trade Statistics. The detailed definitions of the vari- ables used and the specific source from which they were obtained are indicated in Appendix A. The Input-Output Data The input-output data come from a different social accounting system, one in which the concept of output in— cludes all intermediate transactions plus the value added, in contrast to the national accounting system where inter- 62 mediate transactions are deducted. Input-output studies of the Puerto Rican economy be- gan as early as 1949, initiated by the Social Science Research Center of the University of Puerto Rico and super- vised by W. Leontiefff and A. Gosfield, the latter in charge of the statistical work and organization of the re- sults. The study culminated in a 33—order total flow matrix for the fiscal year 1948.18 An Aggregated version of this table was later used in two studies in an updated form (up- dated to 1953) for the purpose of comparing the 1953 and 1963 structures of the Puerto Rican economy. The most important, and by far the most elaborate input-output table developed in Puerto Rico, was that for 1963. The development of this table followed the prin- ciples applied in the accounts of Norway, adapted for the statistics available in Puerto Rico. The study, conducted under the supervision of Mr. Erik Homb from the Central Bureau of Statistics in Norway, followed as closely as possible, the United Nations recommendations.20 Another 18See Amor Gosfield,"Input—Output Analysis of the Puerto Rican Economy," in National Bureau of Economic Research, Input—Output Analysis: An Appraisal (Princeton: Studies of Income and Wealth, Vol. 18, 1955). The author gives a fairly detailed explanation together with some method- ological procedures used in the construction of the tabLebut unfortun- ately does not include the table. 19 20United Nations, Proposals for the Revision of the Social National Accounts, August 1957, E/CN. 3/356. A. L. Ruiz, Op. cit. and R. Weisskoff, op. cit. 68 table of similar making was constructed for 1972. The Norwegian method, as adapted to Puerto Rico is based on the principle that the supply of each commodity from various suppliers is balanced by the total use by various users. The supply at producer's prices is divided into (1) local production; (2) imports; (3) local excise taxes; and (4) Federal (U. S. A.) import duties. In this scheme imports are classified as"competitive" and "non-competitive." Total use is estimated at purchaser prices and is disaggregated into: personal consumption; government consumption; ex- ports; investment in machinery and equipment, in con- struction in three types of inventories; and, finally, in intermediate consumption. Using estimates of profit margins ("markups") these accounts are adjusted to make them com- parable to supply accounts which are valued in producer's prices. The input-output tables for 1963 and 1972 provide the foundation for this part of the study. The tables for these two years are selected because they are the only ones that provide information about the domestic, as well as the total, flows. This separation is very important when the import portion of the total flow is as significant as it is in an Open Puerto Rican economy. 21The Norwegian national accounting system is summarized in T. Schiétx "The Use of Computers in the National Accounts of Norway," Review of Income and Wealth 12 (December 1966): 69 Each set of the available tables for 1963 and 1972 includes the transaction, direct coefficients, inverse co- efficients and matrices for the total flows as well as the domestic flows between 44 sectors in the Puerto Rican econ- omy. These matrices, in producer prices, are available in both current prices and 1963 constant prices. The latter will be used in this study.22 Labor requirements per unit of output for the year 1963 and 1972 are also needed. Those given in A. L. Ruiz's doctoral dissertation are used.23 22The 1973 and 1972 tables, as originally computed, are not exactly similar. However, they were made comparable by A. L. Ruiz, head of the Economic Research unit of the Economic Department of the University of Puerto Rico, tobe used in ongoing research there. This version is the one used in this study. 23Ruiz, Chapter IV. CHAPTER IV STRUCTURAL TRANSFORMATION IN PUERTO RICO: AN OVERALL VIEW An overview of some of the structural transformations which have occurred as the economy Of Puerto Rico under- went economic development is presented in this chapter. The changes perceived are contrasted with the experiences other countries have gone through during the same process and against what can be expected according to accepted theory. A Brief Historical Review of Puerto Rico's Development Strategy The main purpose Of this section is to offer a brief historical overview of the Puerto Rican development strategy} 1Puerto Rican economic development has been reviewed by sev- eral authors. See,for example, Werner Baer, The Puerto Rican Economy and United States Fluctuations (University of Puerto Rico: Social Science Research Center 1962): H. Barton,Puerto Rico's Industrial Development Program,1942-l960(HarvandUni- versity Center for International Affairs 1959); Gordon K.Lewis Puerto Rico, Freedom and Power in the Caribbean (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1963); Lloyd Reynolds and P. Gregory, Wages and Productivity and Industrialization in Puerto Rico (Homewood; Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965); David F. Ross, 322 Long Uphill Path (Puerto Rico; Editorial Edil, Inc., 1949). Before 1940, see Victor S. Clark and Associates, Puerto Rico and Its Problems (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1960). 7O 71 This discussion is restricted to those aspects which are most relevant to an understanding of Puerto Rico's develop- ment prOgram. Special emphasis is placed on the period after World War II when the deveIOpment program took form. A very brief description of the period before 1947 is given as background for understanding the major changes which occurred in the post-war period. The Period Before 1947 This period is divided into two sections. One corres- ponds to what has been called the "stagnation period." The other can be considered a transition before the economy "takes-Off" on the path toward development of the modern economy. Before 1940: The Stagnation Period The island of Puerto Rico was under Spanish rule until 1897 and was integrated into the United States after the SpanishAmerican War of 1898. From 1898 to 1900 she was ruled by a military government which was changed to a civ- ilian one by an act of the United States Congress known as the "Foraker Act." Under this Act, Puerto Rico was in- cluded in the tariff and monetary system of the United States. The "Jones Act" of 1917 gave United States citizen- 2W. W. Rostow, The Stages Of Economic Growth: A Non- Communist Manifesto (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960). 72 ship to the Puerto Ricans and declared the island a terri- tory of the United States, "organized but unincorporated." From an economic viewpoint the two acts had the com- 3 bined effect of: l. The establishment Of a free trade area between the two countries which allowed for the free movement - in either direction - of capital, labor and merchandise and services. 2. Free accessibility of Puerto Rico to United States financial markets. 3. The inclusion of Puerto Rico under the regulation Of United States coastal shipping laws which limit merchandise transportation to and from the island to United States built and owned vessels. The new politico-economic relations had the immediate impact of increasing imports and exports between the two countries and of reducing, in relative terms, trade between Puerto Rico and foreign countries. The value of imports from the United States, in current prices, increased from 6.9 to 100.5 millions of dollars between 1901 and 1940 3For a full discussion of the relationship between Puerto Rico's political status and her economy, see U. S. Congress, Hearipgs before the United States-Puerto Rico Commission on the Status of Puerto Rico: Economic Factors (Washington: U. S. Printing Office, 1966). 73 while imports from foreign countries increased from 1.9 to 6.5 millions Of dollars for the same period. The rela- tive share (in total imports) of imports from foreign countries, dropped from 21.9 percent in 1901 to 6.1 percent in 1940. Likewise, the value of exports to the United States increased from 5.6 millions of dollars in 1901 to 90.6 millions in 1940, while exports to foreign countries decreased from 3.0 to 1.4 millions of dollars. The relative share of exports to foreign countries was reduced from 34.9 to 1.5 percent. The composition of trade between the two countries also changed. The sugar industry was particularly favored by the protection Offered under the American Tarrif system while non-protected industries, like coffee, suffered a sharp decline. Table 4.1 clearly shows these changes. The growth of the needlework industry in the manufacturing sector can also be Observed. The economic activity of this industry was mainly piece-work performed at home by women, an activity that by 1940 provided about 45 percent of manufacturing em- ployment.5 A picture of the economy up to 1940 can best be summar- ized by a view of the industrial structure of the island at 4A. L. Ruiz, "Capital Imports and the Economic Develop- ment of Puerto Rico: Studies in Input-Output Framework"(Ph.D. Dissertation, University Of Wales, England, 1972). 5See Table 4.7 below. .omH .m .amva .mmoua coax Opposm mo xuflmuo>fiss "sash :mmv ucosmofio>oo possefia ca scapm < "spawns Owsosoom m.oumm Opuosm .mmo~nom .m xo>ym= "mumsom 74 oo.ooH on.~w oo.ooH mw.s oo.oo~ mm.v~ q<909 om.mH on.mH oH. Ho.o . . gnozoavooz mw.H om.H om.~ oH.o so.o Ho.o wanna ov.s o~.c om.w ou.o on.v no.c OoomaOH nw.o H5.o os.n 00.0 ow.m vm.o mommmaoz NH.os mm.sm om.oo ~s.e om.s~ Hm.m esmsm Hm.o Nv.c os.HN os.H o~.vo om.m oommou Hench muuomxm HmuOH manomxm “much mahomxm mo accused mo osfim> mo vacuums mo osam> mo ucooaom mo osam> xufiwoseou ovmfi Homfl mawa .Aneszsoe seesase shy coma .Hosfi .mme mo ossos oesoexm sneer oeeose eons: mo ooeoeeooes o>eesfiom--.fi.s mamoo or» oe vacuum assosoom use msma .posvosm use oeoosm coax canons .vnmom mcflsswmm Oowm canons "mumaow mmH mum vma mm em ma unoEumo>cH voxwm mmOHu chm nwm vow NNH mm we moow>hom :H 5mm mmv vvm vow an mmH mwooo eggshzaucoz :H HmH NmH mm 0v on ma mvooo Oanmuzo :H moHH NnoH nmc va oom mHN COMHQESmcou HmuOh HVOfi onoH mmc nmv mwm NHN oEoo:H ofinmmommfla Hmcomhom MHHH omHH Hoe ovv mam mam oEoo:H Hmcomhom mam «mm 0H0 mmv Nam HHN oEoocH uoz mmmfi mama Hmn use mom 1: possess Ofiumosoo mmOHu owed NNHH 0mm on wmm mom nonvOHm HMQOflumz mmonu 55mg whoa mama mmmfi nvma ovma mosHm> «cameo you Hepmowpcm anocoom .floo~ u vmmfi .mswaaov usmumcoo muwmmo pom :MU nnmfi pen mass .momH .mmoH .seoH .osmH neon» Loosen .sszoeo mo neossoeoeH ooooosom meow--.m.e mgmm Ho: :Oflmehomcum m.v ofinwh EOHM woumHSOHmu "mumaom m.oH- N.s H.s m.- m.m proseno>sH ooxse nnoeo oo.- s.s o.o o.o . o.» noos>eom sH s.H H.s e.m s.m s.m noose osssssp-soz sH o.o m.w o.m o.ss ~.s nooou passeso sH m.o o.o o.m s.s o.e soeooeonsou soreness Hseos m.o- o.m m.e m.m m.s oeoosH ososnooneo aseooeoe m.o- H.o o.m m.m m.s oeoosH Hononeoe s.o- s.e o.e s.e w.e oeoosH.soz w.H m.m m.m m.m m «Osmond Owumosoa mmosu o.c- m.e s.e s.m o.~ suppose “stoesoz noose unmaumnma Numfiamooa mcmanmmaa mmmuunvma nvaucvafi Hoquflvcm assocoum nusouo mo ovum euwmmu you .nwommp:OOhom sag mwOflnom wouoofiom meow pom :pzouu mo maoumowusH ufleocoom meow mo cuzoso mo ouemnn.v.v mqm .moeonmenum messooo< Hscofieoz mo xoonuso» .nsosanz noose: "mmumoom mo. we. as. om. osoesoseem House as ucosonmEm weansuommscmz mo onmcm Ha. ss. ms. sN. spouse weepseosmnss: mo oessm new 9. 9 OH. as. om. om. oeseeosooxm prosono>eH mo renew sou as Noe mm» moss finesfiflon .m.= shy mufimwu Mom weapons Oflumosoa mmono OfiHnsmom moseseh coax nonwOfivsu vasoeoom swam: smowcwsoo canons .msma use» .fluww: new OHHnsmom seaflsaeon .mowmsmn .oowm Osgood pom sowumuaamsspmsvsH use suzonu assocoum mo whoumOfivcm meowuu.m.v mam<~ 93 economy during the Nineteen Seventies. In the section be- low the structure of the economy is examined to see how it was transformed while the economy was growing up to 1972, to see if some of the changes help to explain part of the stagnation of the Nineteen Seventies. Changes in the Structure of Production A comparison of the percentage share of groups of in- dustries in the toal domestic net income, for different years, is presented as an indicator of the changes which occurred in the structure of production of the Puerto Rican economy. Table 4.6 shows these distributions for 1940, 1947 1955, 1963, and 1972. The years were chosen to correspond to the end or the beginning of periods of major changes in the strategy of Puerto Rico's development program. There are some discrepancies between the 1940 sec- toral shares shown in this table and those presented for that year in Table 4.2 above. The latter is based on dom- estic income, or the income generated in the geographical area of the country while the former is based on the in- come retained in the area, or net national income. The difference between the two concepts of income is the net effect of payments made to foreign owned factors of produc- tion used abroad. Some outstanding points can be observed in Table 4.6. First, there is the sharp decrease of the agricultural share 94 .mnmfi .muosvonm was osoosm ooam canons .vnnom mewssmfim coax canons "mumaom o.momm o.non~ H.oww o.mom H.mo~ oesHHoo mo neoefifiez as .aeom o.H~ w.o~ s.m H.s m.HH oenenm Hsoa pen pursuancH .ooessee o.o~ ~.o~ m.mH s.w~ s.NH poses m.w H.s s.m o.s s.m possesses senses soreo one soeeseeoeossse m.N e.m m.H e.o m.o asseneosmssoz porno m.m s.m m.~ e.o m.o assesses: one nauseous Hope: m.H o.H n.“ s.o e.o nauseous noose pro Assn .oeoem s.e w.s o.o m.o m.o ofiooeeoru s.o o.o m.o o.o e.o mssansssso use assesses o.o s.o m.o s.o m.o repossess pro neosooee woos. m.s o.s 4.4 m.m w.~ nofieexos one sonnee< ~.e o.o m.o H.~H m.s ooossos one nomssoeom .oooe o.m~ o.m~ o.mH m.w~ s.~H wsseaoonmass: 5w so on m.~ N; 538328 fl.o m.o m.o N.o -- memes: m.m o.s m.oe e.~H o.o~ soroo m.o m.e o.w m.mH H.sH ossonomsm m.n m.- H.mH ~.w~ s.rn oesefisoeeme was“ moms mmmfl seas gems eoeoom .manHHov mo m:OwHHwE was mowwucoouom say NsmH new mama .mmmfl .svma memo» Hmomwm .uoo> on» you fiance use :«mwso Hwfisumsvsu son newusnwsumwn ammusoosoa .OOflm canons mo oeooeH Ofiumosooan.o.v mgm0 socho>oo on» on phenom oweocoom .muwom msficcmfim coax canons "muxsom o.sos o.ooo o.omm o.omm o.~Hm neoxeoz mo noesoeors .aou H.s~ ~.eH w.~H w.- n.4H nooseeom o.o o.o e.o m.s o.m mossessea oefinso soreo use roseseeoensses N.~ m.H 0.0 u- 0.0 cuspmm Hmom new oocmhsmcm .oucmeam m.w~ w.sH m.oH H.4H m.oH opens o.HH s.» m.o ~.m u.m meets: use soesosesnsoo s.~H a.” e.m N.s m.~ msseseosmsssz porno m.e H.s N.» ~.m m.m nfioesoe< one messages s m.H e.m s.s e.w geosoapooz oeo: m.o m.o v.0 e.o o nowseo>om oesosoos<. w.~ o.~ m.m m.N H.m neospoee ooosros one soon H.mH H.oH o.su o.m~ s.oH msessoosmsssz ~.o s.mH ~.wH ~.m~ m.o~ oesefisosem< torso o.s e.s s.HH m.s~ ~.e~ ossoesmsm m.s H.m~ H.om o.wm s.ee oensfieoeem< News moms mmos sees owes noeoom .nmnoxsoz mo mvswmsonu new mowmusoohomv ~50“ 0cm .m00H .mmmH .nvmfi .0v0H memo» Hmumflm .Hmo> may now deuce new sfimflno HmwnumsvcH son cowusnwnumwo ommusoopom .oowa canons ca mnemuom pesoHnamnu.n.v mam0 pocso>oo 0:» on mpsomom Oweocoom .mumom weassmfia coax canons “mumaom H.oN o.~H w.NH s.ma e.HH o.mu “av some oeoesoHQEosa m.He m.me s.mn 0.0e o.~m N.~m s0 room eowusmflowoesa meson Hones own can on so as on pesoHQEoss one ems ooo smm oom Nam eosoaoem mmo saw was ems mso moo ooeoe moons oHNN mmws mums moms owNH smsu eo>o pas om< mo ones» as rosessseoo sees mesa moms mmms sens owns neoeH .mmowmucoonom new mnoxsoz mo mmcmmsona sag mama can .tha .momH .mmmH .500H .0va muse» Hmomflm .oumm ucosonQEOCD new ovum coaummauwpsmm oosom Home; .0902 so Ow< mo mums» ea m:Ompom mo magnum ucoexoflmEmaa.w.v mam owmmwowmom Onam> mummwowmoa osHm> new» 8:030 0230. 3.39.; 39096 .Aoofl u smoa .oeoHHoo :osHHne an osso>0 Nana use moms .mmmH .ssos .oemH mess» finesse .noosooee Hoeomssz mmoao o>wuoommom on» mo ommucoosom we 0:0 oocaamm omens 0cm mpHomEH .munomxm mo osaw>nu.0.v mqm ozu 0:00sfioxo moanu:soo Hoguo 0:0 moumpm 0000:: can on muuomxo mo0sao:Hm .nmumox macaum>0 Ho:uo>o0 one Op phonon ano:oom .0amom w:w::mad ooam canons "000000 0.00H 0.00H 0.00H 0.000H 0.000 0.000 4 deuce uuomxm mo 00x9 .fimawHHo0 mo m:oHHHflE :0 mosam>v 0n0~ 0:: 000H .000H mama» “woman .HwHOH mo mommu:oosom 0:0 o=Hm> Haves .munomxm omw0:m:onoz muos0o90 3oz 0ouooHom 0:: Hm:o«ufi0mnbut.fifi.v mgmv so:so>ou one on unomom oweo:oom .0Hmom w:w::mam coax ouuosm "mumaom o.oo: o.oo: o.oo: o.oo: m.m4om s.om:: m.owm :.smm :om o::o:oo:< s.s: N.o: o.:~ o.m~ o.omm 0.0m: :.s~: w.mw noooe m.o~ :.:m o.mm m.o4 m.mow m.oom o.m- :.~m: no:sss=o-=oz m.m o.m o.~ 4.0 m.mo: N.mm o.s: m.o: stereo m.~ :.m :.m o.: o.:s o.mm o.s: 0.0 noose:::o< :so::uoo:m o.m m.m m.~ m.o :.:s: s.:4 0.4: m.~ oo::ooeoos< 4.:: s.o m.w ~.m 4.s4m w.~:: m.o4 o.s: no:ss:so o.o4 w.O4 :.s4 0.:m 4.040: 0.0s4 4.4sm :.oo: noooo so:o:e:osou Nso: mom: mmo: s4o: «as: non: mmo: s4o: HHOQEH mo oaks kuoe mo ow:u:ouuom os:m> Hench .flmommu:oosom 0:: 0:00:00 mo m:Ow:~me :00 who: pen mom: .mmo: .s4m: neon» :son:s .:oeos or: no oomoesooeoe one o::o> :ouos .m0oou oumw0oEpou:H 0:0 Hmuwmmu .:Osumesm:ou >0 0omemmm:u masons: omw0:mcouoznu.0:.v mgm:ee 4.00 4.44 s.mm w.:m m.mw~ s.om: :.:s 4.0m oeoeo:=om use seos:rosz :.m: s.:: m.:: m.o 4.o~: n.44 4.40 o.o o::oso mxnoz Hospo 0:: m:oo:ow .m0mom o.4: o.o: o.m: s.m: 4.:4: o.sm o.e~ o.:: mon:e::oesm o::ose N.m: s.o: 4.0: m.o ~.os: ~.4o m.~m 4.4 non:eosoeem oes>:ee m.~m o.o~ ~.om 0.00 o.s:m :.No: :.oo 4.0: ome:o::sm :s:oeoeeou use :s:esonos: 4.m 4.0 4.m o.m o.:m m.m: w.o: s.~ o::ose 4.0: 4.m~ 4.s: :.m: m.sm: :.ow o.4m s.o ooo>:ee 4.4m o.s~ w.m~ s.o: N.omm o.~o: 4.m4 4.N: we:oso: s.os o.mo n.4o w.~4 ~.mwo 4.040 0.00: s.mm so:oo=eoo=ou was: mom: was: :40: men: moo: moo: s4o: :mHOH mo ow:u:ooso: os:s> ::HOH p:oEumo>:: MO 0009 .nmommu:oouom 0:: .00: u 400: .mnm::o0 a:mpm:oo mo m:o::::s ::0 000: 0:0 000: .000: .040: mumo> :mom:: .:muo9 mo mowmu:oosom 0:0 o=:0> :muob :: .oo:m ouuozd :: u:ospmo>:: 0:900500 0ox:m mmOhUna.0:.v mqm:uo< p:oEumo>:: .mmowmu:oonom ::v m0o:uo0 0ouoo:om oeom How mp:oEumo>:: 0ox:m mmonu :euoe 0:: u:oem::0m 0:: xuo:::omz .:o:uo:num:ou mo :uzono mo moumm :m:::< ommno>sm oeo>:es 0.0 0.4: 0.0: 0.00 nme:>40 osoeeeo>o0 0.40 0.00 0.00 0.44 so:os:ooemoa 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.44 nosesom :nseoee: 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.00 :400040 :sseooxm 0o nzo:0e: ooz ":mHOH on» mo mowmu:oo000 m< 0.:00: 0.000 4.000 0.:0 0sm oss>:eo 0.00: 0.40 :.04 0.00 00=:>40 peoeseo>o0 0.404 :.:0: 0.00 0.00 so:on:ooesoo 0.00m 0.0:0 :.04: 0.00 noonsom :ssnoss: 0.000: 4.000 0.00 0.00 :400040 :sssoexm 0o 020:0:: 002 ":mnm::o0 mo m:o::::sv mo:::> :mpos :: 00m: 00m: 000: 040: :mom:m .:muoh mo omen:oonom mm .000: 0:0 000: .000: .000: 0000» 0:4 os:s> :sooe 0: noses :so:msu 0o noonsom--.m:.4 0:040 132 of external capital in total capital funds is still larger if one takes into consideration that a significant portion of depreciation charges and undistributed profits, two im- portant sources of local financing, accumulate to foreign firms. The low level of private savings, that were even negative for 1947 and 1972, is evident from the table. A high level of consumption relative to disposable income has kept personal savings low to neutralize business savings. Noticeable also is a steady decrease in the share of public savings as a source of capital funds. Thus, domestic fin- ancing of investment has been very low. The increasing dependence on external capital ob- served in the Puerto Rican economy is contrary to what is expected after economic growth sets in and is maintained for several years. According to Paauw and Fei, the depen- dence on capital inflow should be lessened during the export- substitution phase,34 the state of growth which Puerto Rico has been since 1955. Chenery and Syrquin also found a nega- tive functionalredationship between increases in per capita GNP and changes in capital inflow in the countries included in their study.35 In Table 4.16 the balance of payments for Puerto Rico is brought into the picture by taking together the trade balance, unilateral transfers and capital movements. The 34Paauw and Fei, p. 98. 5Chenery and Syrquin, p. 20. 133 .00::E::00m 0003 0:0: 00 0000 0005000 mo 00:0:00 0:0 0000000 00:000 00:00 mo 000:0:0 0:0 00:: m0:0:000000:0 05000 .oo0:-0v0: .000: .0000000 000 0500:: 00:0 000000 .00000 m::::0:0 00:0 000030 000 0000: 000 000: .00:00>0o 0:0 00 000000 0:50:000 .00000 m::::0:0 00:0 000000 "000300 0: 0 n- -u 0:0:00:Eo 000 000000 00:- 000- 00- 00 00000< 0000000>00 00000 000000 0: 0+0 00000000 00 may 0000000: 002 0400 000 00 00 0000 000000 :0 0000000>00 00000000 0: 0.0 00000000 00 0+0 0000000: 002 0000 000 00 00 uoz .00:050>oz 0000000 0000- 000- 00 - 00- 000000000 002 0:0 0000000 00000 000 00 00 00 0-0 00000< 0000 000000000 004 00 00 0 0:02:00>00 00 0: 0: 0: cm mm00:0:0.00 044 000 00 04 000000 00 000 000 000 00 0:02:00>00 0000000 0000 00 00 00 0 000>000 040 040 0:0 00 :+0 00000< 0000 00>00000 000000000 000 000 000 00 00000 .002 .00000000 000000000: 0000- 000- 000- 000- 0000000 00000 0004 4000 000 004 :-0 0000000 0000 0000 000 000 0+0 0000000 000: 00000 0000 040: .00000000 00 00000005 :00 0000 0:0 000: .000: .0400 00000 000000 .0000 Own—"02.n— EOHM UGM OH mHQQEQ>OZ HMHMQNU 6:5 WHOWWa—NHF HMHOHmfiww—D .QUGdem O‘NHFII.©H.V mqm0u 0:0 00 000000 0:000000 .00:0 000000 .00000 w0:000:0 00:0 000000 0000300 o.mm~c o.mmmm m.mco: m.~0m 0000000 0:000000 00000 o.:ku m.mw:u 0.00 n 0.0: . 0:00: 0:0 m0 0000 0:0 00 0:00 00000: 000000 0.00 :.00 0.0: m.m 0:00: 0:0 m0 0000 0:0 000m 00>:0000 00000: 000000 00:00 0.00: 0.00 0.00: 0.0m 0000000>0u :000000 0:0 0: 0:00 000000:000m 000 00:00:0m .0000: 0.000- 0.00 - 0.00 0.00 000 .0000: 000 00 0000 00000 N.mnom :.:BNN w.:0:: 0.0:0 0000000 :000:00z 00000 N00: mom: mmm: 000: 000: 00000000 00 00000000 000 0000 000 0000 .0000 .0400 0000» 000000 .0000: 000 00 0000 0:0 00 000 000m 00000000 000000 000 0000000 0:000000 00000 .0000000 :000:00z 0000oun.0:.v mqm. 00: 00000 .000. .00000000 0:0 0300:. 0000 000000 .00000 0:00:000 0000 000000 l00m 0000000000 00::0000 0000000: I000 0000—30—00: .. 0000000< 00 _-< 00:00 :0 :30:0 000000500 0000000000 0:0 I000 0000.00.00- 00.~ 0~ o. 00.0 00 o. 00.0 00 0 0 0 0 0000000 00000000=002 .0 00. . N 00. N 0 00. N 0 0 0 N 0000000 000-000 .u .... 00 00 00.. 00 00 00.. 00 00 00.. .v 00 0000000 .0 00.. .0 00 0~.. 00 00 v... 00 00 0... 00 N0 00000:. .0 uvah .«O 0.0-503.09% .m 0... N0 N0 0... 00 00 00.. 00 00 0... 00 00 00000 00.0000 .0 00. 00 00 ~0. 00 00 00. v~ 00 00. 0. 00 0000. 0000:0:. .0 00. 0 0. N0. 00 00 00. .0 00 00.. 00 00 000-0 000-000 .0 0:0-00.0Im 00 000003000 .0 00.. 00 N0 00. 00 .0 .0. 00 00 00. 00 00 000000 000>0u0 .u 00. 00 00 00.. 00 00 00. 00 00 00.. .0 .0 0:00so 0000000. .0 00. q 0 00.. .. 0 00.. 0. 0. 00.. 00 0. 000000 00-.00 .- 0000000000 00 005000000 .0 00. 0. 00 00. .N 00 00. .0 .0 00.. 00 00 00000-50000 0900 .0 3. 0.0 00 8.. 00 00 00.. .0 00 8.. .0. 00 8.00.5080 32000.. .- 0culuo 00000-0: 00 000003000 .N 00.0 oN 0 00.0 0. 0 00.0 .N 0 0~.0 0N v 30.0c. .000000 .0 0... 00 00 00.. 00 00 00.. 00 00 00. 0. 0. 0:0:00o>=. 00000-00 00000 .0 00.. a 0 n... 0 0 on. - . - N - cw..- v.- 0.- mucm>0m 00000-00 00000 .- 0000000l500< .0 00000 .0:00< .0500: 00000 .0300< .05002 0.000 .0300< .0300: 0.000 .0:00< 00'002 : 0 a 0 0 0 a 0 ”6:02 ~quz maEOZ ~E02 \..:00< \.0=00< \.0=00< \.0:00< ~00. 000. 000. 000. N00. 0:0 000. .000. .000. 0000» .000000000 000000000< 00000000 0:0 00000::I500< «00:00—000 00—00000> mo 00:~0> ~0300< 0:0 ~0l002n-.0—.v man44 sectors. These are enumerated in Table 5.1 and classified as primary, manufacturing, or service sectors. The table also shows the value added of each sector as a percentage of total value added, to give an idea of their economic importance. The direct domestic coefficients for 1963 and 1972 are compared by using the scatter diagram shown in Figure 5.1. In this diagram each axis measures the direct input 6In the input-output analysis total output includes that delivered to intermediate demand as well as deliveries to final demand. 164 coefficient value for a particular year; the 45 - degree line, which tells when the coefficients for the two years are identical, indicates whether the coefficients are larger for one year than for another. Sectors with coefficient: larger in 1972 than in 1963 appear above the 4S - degree line and the converse is true for points below the diagonal. Logarithmic scales are used, so that the distance from the diagonal measures the relative rate of coefficient change. In Figure 5.1 each sector is identified by the number in Table 5.1. It is obvious in Figure 5.1 that 30 of the 44 sectors increased their direct coefficients, while only 14 reduced them. Moreover, for most of the 30 sectors with increased coefficients, the change was more than 25 percent as can be discerned by the distance of each sectors from the diagonal. These changes give a clear indication of increased interde- pendence. An interesting point from Figure 5.1 is that of the seven manufacturing industries that reduced their direct co- efficients, five are in the agriculture based manufacturing sectors. The reduction in the coefficients of these sectors matched the drop in primary agriculture activity, as in- dicated by the decrease in their share of value added, shown in Table 5.1. In the non-agricultural manufacturing group, which includes the new manufacturing promoted under the government development program, most sectors experienced 1655 TABLE 5.1.--Sectora1 Value Added as a Share of Total Value Added, 44 Sectors, Years 1963 and 1972 (in percentages). Sector 1963 1972 Change Primary Production 9.04 3.01 -6.03 1. Sugarcane 3.22 0.38 -2.84 2. Other Agriculture 5.55 2.51 -3.04 3. Mining 0.27 0.12 -0.15 Manufacturing and Construction 29.48 31.05 1.57 4. Construction 6.67 6.76 0.09 5. Dairy Products 0.42 0.30 -0.12 6. Bakery Products 0.41 0.43 0.02 7. Sugar Refining 1.77 0.08 -1.69 8. Malt Beverages 1.12 0.33 -0.79 9. Alcoholic Beverages 2.98 2.11 -0.87 10. Soft Drinks 0.25 0.36 0.11 11. Other Food 1.03 0.63 -0.40 12. Tobacco Products 1.09 1.20 0.11 13. Apparel and Textiles 3.72 4.55 0.83 14. Furniture and Wood 0.59 0.48 -0.11 15. Paper Products 0.27 0.27 0.00 16. Printing and Publishing 0.50 0.41 -0.09 17. Chemicals 1.59 4.60 3.01 18. Petroleum refining 1.10 0.97 -0.13 19. Leather Products 0.65 0.43 -0.22 20. Stone glass 1.38 1.15 -0.23 21. Primary Metals 0.17 0.19 0.02 22. Fabricated Metals 0.57 0.88 0.31 23. Nonelectrical Machinery 0.22 0.23 0.01 24. Electrical Machinery 1.57 2.30 0.73 25. Transportation Equipment 0.05 0.07 0.02 26. Professional Instruments 0.54 1.25 0.71 27. Misc. Manufacturing Industries 0.82 1.06 0.24 Services 61.48 65.94 4.46 28. Transportation 5.04 4.26 -0.78 29. Communication 1.24 1.50 0.26 30. Electricity and Gas 2.27 3.56 1.29 31. Aqueduct 0.67 0.74' 0.07 32. Trade 18.48 18.77 0.29 33. Finance 1.74 2.41 0.67 34. Insurance 0.62 0.89 0.27 35. Real Estate 7.47 11.91 4.44 36. Hotels 1.05 0.92 -0.13 37. Personal Services 0.67 0.60 -0.07 38. Business Services 1.20 1.07 -0.13 39. Amusement and Recreation 1.60 0.41 -l.19 40. Health Services 1.62 1.55 40.07 41. Other Services 4.03 3.46 -0.57 42. Commonwealth Government 8.85 10.31 1.46 43. Municipal Government 0.99 1.21 0.22 44. Federal Government 3.94 2.38 1.56 TOTAL 100.00 100.00 100.00 166 0 Agriculture based manufactures 0 Non agriculture manufactures and construction L 0 Primary products I __ 0 Services (notNéniD'o I972 DIRECT INTERMEDIATE INPUT COEFFICIENTS 01 .l .'2 .3 .1; .5? A .i .é ér'o I963 DIRECT INTERMEDIATE INPUTS COEFFICIENTS FIGURE 5.l Sums of Direct Intermediates Inputs Coefficients From All Sectors For I963 and l972,Primary, Manufacturing and Service Sectors. (Dollars per dollar of Total output ) - 167 large increases in their coefficients. Nine out of 15 in- dustries in this group more than doubled their direct co- efficients. On the other hand, only two sectors of the non- agricultural manufacturing group, paper products and primary metals, decreased their coefficients. It is interesting also that eight of the non-agricultural manufacturing sectors that increased their coefficients, according to Figure 5.1, at the same time increased their share of value added. This finding indicates that those were dynamic sectors which sim- ultaneously increased their direct contributions to the economy and improved their capacity to stimulate the contri- butions of other sectors. These sectors were apparel and textiles, chemicals, fabricated metals, non-clerical mach- inery, electrical machinery, transportation equipment, pro- fessional instruments and miscellaneous manufacturing. Seven of 17 sectors in the service industries group, according to their position below the diagonal in Figure 5.1, decreased their interdependence with the rest of the economy. The large drop in the coefficient of the insur- ance sector, which was reduced by about two-fifths, and coefficient of "other services" which were cut in half, is significant. The fact that the share of value added in the insurance sector increased, as is shown in Table 5.1, indicates that part of the coefficient decrease was due to a larger portion of the activity being performed within the firms composing the sector. Interesting also is the 168 fact that the coefficients of hotels and amusement and recreation diminished while their share of value added also went down. The two sectors are closely related to tourism, which is supposed to have a propulsive role in the economy, according to the expectations of the new development program. This finding suggests that this pro- pulsion has not yet been realized. A definite conclu- sion, however, can not be made because other important ben- efits of tourism, such as tourist expenditures on the island, must also be considered. In contrast to these seven sectors, eight service sectors increased their direct technological coefficients while at the same time improving their share of value added. These sectors, which can be considered dynamic, are con- centrated in the utilities and public administration activities and are strongly dependent on central government expenditure decisions. The direct coefficients, analyzedsuafar, take into consideration only the first round effects of production increases in one sector on the rest of the economy. There are later impacts derived from the increased production arising from the first round. Hence, the domestic integra- tion of the structure of production can best be evaluated by an index that takes into consideration both the sector's direct and its indirect output responses to changes in demand. Such an index can becmtmhmd from the modified 169 Leontieff inverse explained in Chapter III. This index has been called a total backward linkage index to stress the fact that it measures the direct plus indirect produc- tion required from each sector per dollar of output delivered to final demand.7 Table 5.2 illustrates the total backward production linkage indexes for the 44 sectors of the Puerto Rican economy for 1963 and 1972. Again, from this point of view, a considerable increase in the domestic integration of the economy is evident. Only 12 of the sectors experienced a reduction of their linkage indexes. Four of these sectors are agriculture based manufacture, six belong to the ser- vice group and two to the new manufacturing industries. It is interesting that other food and hotels, whose direct coefficients in Figure 5.1 decreased, experienced an in- direct increase large enough to make their total linkage indexes go up. As expected, the linkage indexes for the agriculture based manufacturing industries were very high, sectors that have decreased rapidly in economic importance as agricultural activity has shrunk. A recuperation of these sectors, with a strategy more favorable to agriculture, would undoubtedly have a large impact on the domestic economy. A sign of favorable structural Change is the consider- able improvement in the domestic integration of most of the new manufacturing sectors. Their linkage indexes have gone 7See Pan Yotopoulos and Jeffrey B. Nugent, "A Balanced Growth Version of the Linkage Hypothesis: A Test" Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (May 1973): p. 61. 170 .chlev .euOu ea vouo>..oa «amuse we an..ov you unaware» :o.uo:voua uuou.v=. mans uuou.v ugh: as. an. - 4... .u.m .... o~.. mo~.. an... ecu-ucosoo .4uoeoa nu. ma. - o..4 ma.4 .~.. 0... ~.o.. on... «nu-ecosou .4a.u.::: Na. .4. - 4... .o.m mo.. oo.. as... ea... ecu-auosoo £3.4osee-uou 4... so. a... no.4 an. o¢~. - mo... ..4.. 449..»om coguo no. 4.. - .m.4 a... o... 5a.. .84.. 4o... .49..»4m au.4o= am. no. - me.4 no.4 .4. .mo. - o.o.. moo.. no.344tuoa Sconces-4 4a.. a.. ao.4 ~m.4 mm. .ao. - a~4.. ca4.. noo.suom 444:..au nu. Nn. - cm.4 ~m.4 ao.. oo.. oa4.. ea... 4.4.suom .4go4uoa as. ac. - mo.4 ~..4 .o.. ~.c. 4.4.. o.4.. 4.ouo= o... «4. .m.m oc.m ea. .4c. - 49... ..n.. 4.43». .44: as. .5. - eo.4 n... ma. mam. - .44.. ~aa.. oucacanc. as. so. - .c.4 o... 4... a... an... ..~.. oo=4=.a me. «a. - a... 4... oo.. ace. .4... 4.... ounce .o. .m. - 4~.m a... ma.. 4a.. .o~.. 4m... suaeoae< an. .a. - .e.4 ~o.m m... ~a.. omn.. 4e... .4e 4:4 .u.u.euuo.m no. 4.. - o4.m a... .... .4.. can.. mm... so.u4u.==n-ou 8. 2. - 3.4 :.m a. 3.. - 34.. 43.. 8.349.845»... $00158 on. m...- o4.4 4a.. a... m... 4a4.. .4... 44.uunse:. 4:.usuoauacuz .44.: 4.. No..- om.4 .o.. 4... a... ao4.. nu... nusnnuuune. .4co.4nocoua on. .0. - o..4 nc.4 o... 4... .a... no... ecu-:.:em so.eauuoa4=uch as. .N. - 94.. .o.m ao.. .4o. a.n.. an~.. auo=.:o.x .4u.c.uo.m an. as. - 04.4 no.. m... 49.. 4.... .N... sue-.aonx .4u.cuoo.o=oz ms. nu. - oc.m a... m... a... .mn.. .4... 4.43m: ecu-u..a-a c... we. .m.m mm.4 .o. o... - n4~.. 404.. 4.434: seen... ~°.. ... .a.4 on.4 ao.. m~.. 0.... .9... «44.nocouu an. a.. - a... aa.m 4... mo.. 0.4.. .4... auuaeoua cone-o. ma. om..- 45.4 m~.o c4.. Q44. 40... o.... 4:.e.uo¢ nso.ouuo. Na. 44. - an.m .a.m o... as». .44.. on... 4.4u.-o:u mg. on. - ”0.4 n4.m o... a... ~m4.. m.~.. 4:.nu..a=a 4:4 4:.u=.ua no. a~. - 4n.m ~o.m as. m.°. - 0.4.. m.4.. nuuaeoua scan. as. ea. - oo.4 N... 44.. a... .N4.. am... noon ecu oueu.=.=a as. we. - an.m .m.m a... 4... .04.. a4... .4..uuop 4:4 .ouaaa< ma. mm. . ao.4 co.m ea. omo. - ..m.. 4.m.. 4uueeou. coo-ace as. so. - an.4 an.4 .c.. cNO. am¢.. an... coca coauo .°.. co. .n.4 a~.4 a... a... .mo.. n4e.. 4.=.ua Scam 8.. 3. - 2... 2.... a... 4.... - v.3. 3...... 49-828: 3.2.32 .a. mo. - ac.4 ~o.n 4... a... ..a.. .44.. 4444.4)». 3.4: co. co. - .o.n .~.4 ~... a... 4.~.~ 4oa.. 4:.:.4oa .4aea no.. N.. so.” 4... ea. ~ac. - 440.. mm... nauseous sue... .°.. no. ...4 c..4 we. 40.. - .mc.. .49.. nauseous .c.4a u=.u=uuuu::ax ~a. 4n. . no.4 an.4 mo.. 4... 4mo.. .4... =e.»u:uuncoo me. a.. - ~a.n ...4 .o.. ~4a. as... .00.. 4=.:.x as. am. - 4a.4 n... o... 4... no... em... oueu.=u.uu< scape 4.. on. - ma.4 4a.. m... a... no... o.~.. ocean-uam 28.3.54 o...¢ ouc4gu ~ae. moo. a...“ cue-so «as. nee. noo.\~ao. noo.\~aa. cease» mecca counuoan.a co.uo=voua u.unoloo execs. ouc.c.. .aueh :e.uo:uoua o.unoleo .~no. vac moo. nude» .nuOuoom vv .comnuonn.a we non=~ as. now:— ouaucua unuOh couuuaioum ouuoolunai.n.m nanm pounwwozm 5. am on.. com. oo4. .ou m m o.o. ..m. hon. moo.>som a N nmo. MON. OOH. oumumm Ham“ v.3 OUGMHSWGH «Guyana.— o . mmo. m... on.. oomph . . ..o.- C4m. .mm. so.o.oooo.m one use .ooaooeo< . . moo.u man. Now. :ofipmofiqsaaou can no.9muhommcmnh . o. one. ham. .4N. moo.>Aom o o ~mo.- moo. 4.o.. mooooooa woo. ooz . a 404. aoo.. moo. mooooouo oooeoop one soon 0. m. mm.. 4am. o... wo.A=ooemo:az o . 4cm. ooh. No4. :o.ooooom:oo o . m4N. mom. mmm. w:.=.z o N com. oam. omm. ohao.oo.um< mommonooo mommouucH owcmsu mum. mom. mucoflowmmoou ecu mowcwcu mucofiofimmoou on» mo o:.m> souoom punk mnouoom mo Honasz i .anu mam mom. whom» .vcmama Hmcwm ou moho>fl.oa usmpao mo HmHHDD you manna. weakens. oumwwoahousm poohwwcH mafia poohwnii.m.m mamoo on» on phenom owsoaoom .vheom wcfisanm oowm canons "mumaom m.e o..~ N... ~m.o eeonoonn oonnooemnnez nonno one ennonnnnen. o.e .m.~ mm.. eo.o snonnnoez one e.eooz e.e .e.~ 4e.. mo.o eoonoonn eee.o one se.u .onoum ..e oe.. ae.o ~4.o eoonoonn nonoeo. e.e oo.~ e~.. no.0 eeonoono .eoonono N.e me.~ me.. eo.o en.on.no one euonoonn oo...< one noneo 4.e .o.. eo.o m4.o onno.nnnn one ooo: .noonn. ~.m 4e.. No.. em.o .onenn< ..e oo.. oo.. e4.o mo..oxoe m.o a... oe.o me.o eoonoonn oooeooe e.o 4N.~ .N.. eo.o eoonoonn oonon.. one ooon omnenu no ooen mam. moo. one. .n:::< omnho>< Houoom .efihumnmam .oweucoohom :. owneso mo open one an..oo :. mwcwnunov mum. one mom. .vmm. .spsonu mo apex .e:=:< oueno>< one whouoom .e.Aumsv:H wcwhsuoemssez oouooHow oaom you mwcfinuem ».uao: ownho>aom o.vm o..m m.mm m.mm 5.00 o.oo. mnflasuoemsnn: ... t m.m. v... v.. . o..o. o.oo. nowuosapmcou o.v r w.o o.o o.oom.o.t o.ooo... o.oo. wn.=.2 m.n r m.o t m.o o.mm . c.0o t o.oo.r opsu.so.am< oasposhum a. menace :. .enoe oasuosnum onesoo .npoh ownenu op can ownesu on one :. omnegu a. emcenu Aouoom owceno mo coasom mo omeucooaoa m< owcego .muob m.houoom mo ownucooaom m< .mnopoom mo mmsoao o>wm .owcenu mo consom one mo oweucooaod me new aouoom one mo owcmso Heuop one mo ammucooaom mm .cowuosvopd mo chauoshum one n. eowneno one oneEon n. eoenenu on one .eeo. on moo. none .onneno n. owneno--.o.m mnehow mo. r 0m. mm. «amuse .nuob e muaoaxm on o.nmpsnweuu< unease v.0mo. w.nwm. v.5om muaomxm op oHQeuanfiuuu< «amuse .euoh ~.N.o~ m.wmmm n.0mm. unease .muoh mafia3uoemsenz 00. t No. mo. unease .muoh m muaonxm op o.nmp=nouuu< unease n... r m.m. 0.mN muaonxm ow o.neu:p.aup< unease .nuob n.0nm ..0.m m.mnm unease .euOH :owuosaumeou no. am. e., onnono .eeoe e ennonxm on o.eeone.noe< unnnno 0.. v.o m.~ muaomxm op oHAepsnoauu< unease .nuob n.o ..0. w.m. undone .enoe m:.n.: mo. . on. me. undone .enoe e eunonxm on o.nennn.nnn< undone e.ee - ..me o.e~. mononxm on o.eenne.nno< onnnno .eeoe m.n¢ t ..wm~ 0.mw~ «amuse .sHOF on:u.:o.nm< oeneno «no. moo. .o.>.oo< one noooom .am.eawooo one mun..oo mo meow..wa so. muouoom mo museum xwm .Nnm. one moo. eneo» .o..en one oononooo.n .eononxm on e.eeene.neo< ennuno one onnono .eeoe--.~..m m.nn. o.u.e-on enouu .a ....... .....4. ....... .ooe.e.. .44.... ..e.... ...o... .ee.... .oeo.~. 64o. e... eon. - .Ne. - ..o. - 4... - ..e. - e.e. .on. - 4eo. e... - un.>4. o.u.e1on ..ono .4 ca.»a..!3< .. an. en .e N. .e u N2.... 2:. ..>e.. >e. enaonnoo :iLIIDIFEIN FIDEI.IDI.C ‘.I ’U.'tl D... ID. Ell Fl .‘I’ I. 1!. 0.1-1.4!.."1 '1 detainees... .nnauoaum «55.3.... 32.47.... 0..- .omneuoum me 28:25.. ea..nouuourr...< 3:... BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Acharya, Shankar N. and Hazari, Bharat R. "Linkages and Imports: A Comparative Study of India and Pakistan." The Journal of Development Studies. 8 (October 1971): 107-15. Agustinovics, Maria. "Method of International and Intertemporal Comparison of Structure." In Contributions to Input-Output Analysis. Vol. 1, pp. 249-69. Edited by Anne P. Carter and A. Brody. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1970. Baer, Werner. "Puerto Rico: An Evaluation of a Successful Development Program." Quarterlngournal of Economics. 73 (1959): 645-71. The Puerto Rican Economy and the United States Fluctuations. University of Puerto Rico: Social Science Research Center, 1962. Baer, Werner and Herve, Michael E. A. "Employment and Industrial- ization in Developing Economies." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 80 (February 1966): 88-107. Baquero, Jenaro. "La Importacion de Fondos Externos y la Capacidad Absorbente de Nuestra Economia." Revista de Ciencias Sociales. (March-June 1963). Barna, Tibor, ed. Structural Interdepgndence and Economic Develop: ment: Proceedings of an International Conference on Input- Output Techniques. London: Macmillan 6 Co., 1963, . The Structural Interdependence of the Economy. New York: John Wiley 8 Sons, Inc., 1954. Barton, H. C. Puerto Rico's Industrial Development Program, 1942- 1960. Harvard University: Center for International Affairs, 1959. Bautista, Romeo M. "Development and Trade in the Small Open Economy: A Theoretical Treatment." Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University, 1971. Beckford, George L. Persistent Poverty: Underdevelopment in Plant- ation Economies of the Third World. New York: Oxford University Press, 1972. 269 270 "Caribbean Rural Economy." in Caribbean Economy. pp. 77- 90. Edited by George L. Beckford, Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research, University of the West Indies, 1975. Bhalla, A. S. "A Disaggregative Approach to Employment in LDCs." Journal of Development Studies. 10 (October 1973): 50-63. "The Role of Services in Employment Expansion." International Labor Review. 101 (May 1970): 519—39. Boucher, Michel. "Some Further Results in the Linkage Hypothesis." Qparterly Journal of Economics. 90 (May 1976): 313-18. Brookfield, Harold. Interdependent Development. London: Methuen 6 Co. Ltd., 1975. Bruno, Michael. Interdependence, Resource Use and Structural Change in Israel. Jerusalem: Bank of Israel, Special Studies No. 2, 1962. Buttler, Friederich. Growth Pole Theory and Economic Development. Westmead: D. C. Heath Ltd., 1975. Cameron, Burgess. Input-Output Analysis and Resource Allocation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1968. Carter, Anne P. Structural Change in the American Economy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970. Carter, Anne P. and Brady, A., eds. Contributions to Input-Output Analxsis. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co., 1970. Chenery, Hollis B. "Application of Interindustry Analysis to Problems of Economic Development." In The Structural Inter- dependence of the Economy. Edited by Tibor Barna. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1954. "Comparative Advantage and Development Policy." American Economic Review. 51 UMarch 1961): 18-51. "Patterns of Industrial Growth." The American Economic Review. 50 (September 1960): 624-53. Chenery, Hollis B. and Clark, Paul G. Interindustry Economics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1959. Chenery, Hollis, Shishido, Shuntaro, and Watanabe, Tsunehiko. "The Pattern of Japanese Growth, 1914-1954." Econometrica. 30 (January 1962): 98-139. 271 Chenery, Hollis and Syrquin, Moises. Patterns of Development 1950- 1970. London: Oxford University Press, 1975. Chenery, Hollis and Taylor, Lance. "Development Patterns: Among Countries and Over Time." The Review of Economics and Statistics. 50 (November 1968): 391-416. Chenery, Hollis B. and Watanabe, Tsunehiko. "International Comparisons of the Structure of Production." Econometrica. 26 (October 1958): 487-521. "Competitive Positions of Manufacturing Industries." Puerto Rico: Industrial Development Administration, 1975 (mimeographed). Consejo, Financiero del Gobernador. El Desarrollo Economico de Puerto Rico: Una Estrategiapara 1a Proxima Decada. Puerto Rico: Editorial Universitaria, Universidad de Puerto Rico, 1976. Curet Cuevas, Eliezer. E1 Desarrollo Economico de Puerto Rico: 1940 a 1972. Puerto Rico: Management Aid Center, Inc., 1976. Demas, William G. "Situation and Change." in Caribbean Economy, pp. 61-76. Edited by George L. Beckford Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social Economic Research, University of the West Indies, 1975. Demas, William G. The Economics of Development in Small Countries with Special Reference to the Caribbean. Toronto: McGill University Press, 1965. Eckaus, R. S. "The Factor Proportions Problems in Underdeveloped Areas." American Economic Review. 45 (1955): 539-65. ECLA. A Contribution to Economic Integration in Latin America. New York: United Nations, 1961. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. "Private Investment and the Industrialization of Puerto Rico." Monthly Review. 42 (May 1960): 68-74. Fei, John C. and Ranis Gustav. "A Model of Growth and Employment in an Open Economy: The Cases of Korea and Taiwan." Journal of Development Studies. 11 (January 1975): 32-63. Development of the Labor Surplus Economy. Homewood, 111.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1964. 272 Fogel, Robert W. "The Reunification of Economic History with Economic Theory." American Economic Review. 55, Supplement (1955): 92-98. Freyre, Jorge. External and Domestic Financing of the Economic Development of Puerto Rico. San Juan: University of Puerto Rico Press, 1969. Furtado, Celso. "Capital Formation and Economic Development." In The Economics of Underdevelopment. Edited by A. Agarwala and S. P. Singh. New York: Oxford University Press, 1963. Development and Underdevelopment. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1964. Economic Development of Latin America: A Survey from Colonial Time to the Cuban Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970. Galenson, W. "Economic Development and the Sectoral Expansion of Employment." International Labor Review. 87 (June 1963): 505-19. Gilmour, James M. Spatial Evolution of Manufacturing in Southern Ontario 1851—1891. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1972. Gosfield, Amor. "Input-Output Analysis of the Puerto Rican Economy." In Input-Output Analysis: An Appraisal. National Bureau of Economic Research. Princeton: Studies of Income and Wealth, Vol. 18, 1955. Hansen, Bent. A Survey of General Equilibrium Systems. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1970. Haring, Joseph E. "External Trade as an Engine of Growth." Economia Internazionale. 14 (1961): 97-118. Hazari, Bharat R. and Krishnamurty, J. "Employment Implications of India's Industrialization: Analysis in an Input-Output Framework." The Review of Economics and Statistics. 52 (May 1970): 181-86. Hibben, Thomas. Industrial Development of Puerto Rico and the Virgin Islands of the United States. Washington: Caribbean Commission, Report of the United States Section, 1948. Hirshman, Albert 0. The Stratpgy of Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1958. 273 Ingram, J. C. "Some Implications of the Puerto Rican Experience." In International Finance, pp. 87-104. Edited by R. N. Cooper. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1969. Ingram, James C. "State and Regional Balance of Payments Mechanism." QuarterlyiJournal of Economics. 73 (November 1959): 619-32. Jones, Leroy P. Public Enterprises and Economic Development: The Korean Case. Seoul: K. D. 1. Press, 1975. "The Measurement of Hirshmanian Linkages." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 90 (May 1976): 323-33. Jorgenson, D. W. "The Development of a Dual Economy." Economic Journal. 71 (June 1961): 309-34. Kelley, Allen C. and Williamson, Jeffrey C. "Modelling Economic Development and General Equilibrium Histories." American Economic Review. 65, Supplement (1973): 450-58. Lastra, Carlos. The Impact of Minimum Wages on a Labor-Oriented Industgy. Puerto Rico: Government Development Bank, Technical Paper No. 1, 1964. Laumas, Prem S. "The Weighting Problem in Testing the Linkage Hypothesis: Comment." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 90 (May 1976): 308-12. ' Leontieff, Wassily W. "Exports, Imports, Domestic Output, and Employment." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 60 (February 1946): 171-93. . Ipput-Output Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 1966. Leontieff, Wassily W. et a1. Studies in the Structure of the American Economy. New York: Oxford University Press, 1953. Levitt, Kari and Best, Lloyd. '"Character of Caribbean Economy." In Caribbean Economy, pp. 34-60. Edited by George L. Beckford. Kingston, Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research, University of the West Indies, 1975. Lewis, W. Arthur. "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor." Manchester School of Economics and Social Science. 22 (1954): 139-91. Lewis, Gordon K. Puerto Rico, Freedom and Power in the Caribbean. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1963. 274 Martinez, Francisco. "External Trade as an Instrument of Economic Development in Puerto Rico." Puerto Rico: Puerto Rico Planning Board, 1974. (Mimeographed). Mathur, P. N. G Bharadwaj, R., eds. Economic Analysis in Input- Output Framework. Poona, India: Input-Output Research Association, 1967. Meyer, John R. and Conrad, Alfred H. "Economic Theory, Statistical Inference and Economic Theory." Journal of Economic History. 17 (1957): 524-53. Miernyk, William H. The Elements of Input-Output Analysis. New York: Random House, Inc., 1965. Mingo, John J. "Capital Importation and Sectoral Development: A Model Applied to Postwar Puerto Rico." American Economic Review. 64 (June 1974): 273-90. Nurkse, Ragnar. Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries and Patterns of Trade and Development. New York: Oxford University Press, 1953. Paauw, Douglas and Fei, John C. H. The Transition in Open Dualistic Economies: Theory and Southeast Asian Experience. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1973. Polenske, Karen R. and Skolka, Jiri V., eds. Advances in Input— Output. Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Publishing Co., 1976. Rao, V. V. "Intersectoral Relationship and Structural Change in West Malasia." Malayan Economic Review. 17 (October 1972): 40-65. Rasmussen, P. Norregard. Studies in Intersectoral Relations. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., 1956. Reynolds, Lloyd. "Labor and Employment in a Labor Surplus Economy." American Economic Review. 55 (March 1965): 19-39. Reynolds, Lloyd G. and Gregory Peter. Wages, Productivity, and Industrialization in Puerto Rico. Homewood, I11.: Richard 1D. Irwin, Inc. for the Economic Growth Center, Yale University, 1965. Riedel, James. "A Balance-Growth Version of the Linkage Hypothesis: A Comment." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 90 (May 1976): 319-22. "Factor Proportions, Linkages and the Open Developing Economy." Review of Economics and Statistics. 57 (November 1975): 487-94. 275 Roemer, Michael. Fishipg_for Groyth. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970. Ross, David F. The Long Uphill Path. Puerto Rico: Editorial Edil, Inc., 1949. v'fi Rostow, W. W. The Staggs of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960. Ruiz, Angel L. "Capital Imports and the Economic Development of Puerto Rico: Studies in Input-Output Framework." Ph.D. dissertation. University of Wales, England, 1976. Enfoque de Insumo-Producto para Determinar una Politica de Substitucion de Importaciones en Puerto Rico. Serie de Ensayos y Monografias No. 3, Departamento de Economia, Universidad de Puerto Rico, 1977. Ruiz, Angel L., Zalacain, Fernando y Bofill Jaime. "La Medicion de la Productividad en Puerto Rico." Puerto Rico: Consejo Asesor del Gobernador Sabre Politica Laboral, Informs Tecnico No. 1, 1976. (Mimeographed). Saigal, J. C. The Choice of Sectors and Regions. Rotterdam: Rotterdam University Press, 1965. Schictz, T. "The Use of Computers in the National Accounts of Norway." Review of Income and Wealth. 12 (December 1966): 311-33. Schultz, Siegfried. "Intersectoral Comparison as an Approach to the Identification of Key Sectors." In Advances in Input-Output Analysis, pp. 137-60. Edited by Karen R. Polenske and Siri V. Skolka. Cambridge, Mass.: Balinger Publishing Co., 1976. Seers, Dudley. "The Stages of Economic Development of a Primary Producer in the Twentieth Century." The Economic Bulletin of Ghana. (1963): 57-69. Sen, Amartya K., ed. Growth Economies: Selected Readingg. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1970. Seymour, Harris. International and Regional Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1957. Some Key Issues of Industrial Development Strategy. Puerto Rico: Industrial Development Administration, 1974 (Mimeographed). Sung-Hwan, Ho. "Korea's Transition to Export-Substitution Growth (1963-1970): Input-Output Analysis." Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University, 1976. 276 Taylor, Milton. "Industrial Tax Exemption in Puerto Rico." National Tax Journal. 7 (September 1954): 359-71. Tidrick, Gene M. "Wage Spillover and Unemployment in a Wage-Gap Economy: The Jamican Case." Economic Development and Cultural Change. 23 (January 1975): 306-24. Tobin, James. "Report to the Governor: The Committee to Study Puerto Rico's Finances." Puerto Rico, 1975. United Nations, Statistical Office. Classification of Commodities By Industrial Origip; Relationship of the Standard International Trade Classification to the International Standard Industrial Classification. Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 43, 1966. U. 5. Congress. Hearings Before the United States-Puerto Rico Commission on the Status of Puerto Rico: Economic Factors. Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1966. Vietorisz, Thomas. "Dependents vs. Autonomous Export Development and the Wage Level in Puerto Rico." Puerto Rico: Inter-Agency Strategy Committee of the Finance Council, 1975. (Mimeo- graphed). Weisskoff, Richard. Colonial Industrialization in the Caribbean: The Economic Development of Puerto Rico. Iowa State University, Department of Economics, forthcoming. Weisskoff, Richard and Wolf, Edward. "Development and Trade Defendence: The Case of Puerto Rico, 1948-1963." The Review of Economics and Statistics. 57 (November 1975): 470-77. "Linkages and Leakages: Industrial Tracking in an Enclave Economy." Economic Development and Cultural Changg, 25 (1976) 607-28. Wuu-Lang, Lin. "Economic Interaction in Taiwan: A Study of Sectoral Flows and Linkages." Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, 1973. Yotopoulos, Pan A. and Nugent, Jeffrey B. "A Balanced Growth Version of the Linkage Hypothesis: A Test." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 86 (May 1973): 157-72. "In Defense of a Test of the Linkage Hypothesis: A Response." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 90 (May 1976): 334—43.