6507 mass-a -- 1 ,.. q E '1; T“ f: E; 1 m A E ,z. Mw‘rrv‘m ..:;.v:-~,~-: This is to certify that the thesis entitled ‘KOCIA’L (rm—Mat: bib OccuPHw/vM Mag/LI7V. m UteA—w ”Zine/4 ’ f presented by PFMPEL/hv/ Mun/ME % ‘I has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for M, A degreein ICC/O (—0 d f Date 3 / IX 0-7639 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution MSU RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to remove this checkout from LIBRARIES w your record. FINES wiH * be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. \71‘ AUG 0 7 2007 I .' l U I L SOCIAL CHANGE AND OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY IN URBAN ZAMBIA BY Pempelani Oliver Mufune A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS Department of Sociology '1982 ABSTRACT SOCIAL CHANGE AND OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY IN URBAN ZAMBIA BY Pempelani Oliver Mufune This thesis deals with the effect of rapid social change as represented by a new political order and dependent industri- alization (and their associated effects on societal institu- tions) on intragenerational and intergenerational occupational mobility. Mobility is conceived of as movement of individuals between and through levels of a society's social stratifica- tion. The literature on social mobility is dominated by two schools. These are the status attainment and opportunity schools. ’ We have summarized the main ideas from the two schools. The difference between the two schools stem from their different focus. The opportunity school's researchers focus is on rates of mobility while the focus of researchers in status attainment is on distribution of individuals among positions. We argue that the two schools also converge in important respects, such that it is possible to derive a dynamic model which links op- portunity structures to individual attributes in the attainment of positions. In the second chapter, we deal with socio-historical background of the Zambian situation and the specification of Pempelani Oliver Mufune age cohort categories, investigating the link between occu- pational demands and educational production as related to po- litical, urbanization and dependent industrialization process- es. The cohorts are derived such that they reflect changes in occupational demands and labour market structures. In the third chapter, we state our problem of investi- gation. After addressing debates on processes of democrati- zation and crystallization of opportunity in the third world, we face the underlying question of how the changing character of societal institutions affect patterns of occupational mo- bility. We break up this question into three hypotheses which we believe to be testable through cohort analysis. The cre- dential inflation hypothesis predicts that as the amount of education in society increases, it will lead to increases in education needed on the part of those aspiring to fill certain occupations. The second hypothesis predicts that the influence of fathers in the occupational and educational achievements will be much stronger in the younger generation as patterns of social stratification consolidate. The third hypothesis predicts that occupational mobility will be greatest in the older population because these entered the labor market when it was changing from agricultural to industrial based occupa- tions. To test these hypotheses, we utilized data collected in Zambia (1973) by Professor David Wiley. We focused our attention on the random sample of 884 males. Path models were utilized to test structural equations as specified in the Pempelani Oliver Mufune Statistical Package for Social Sciences. We also used Zero- order correlations and cross tabulation. We constructed a prestige scale, to use in the path model, based on Lay's (1973) "Zambian Scale" and Treiman's (1977) "International Standard Occupation Prestige Scale." The last chapter deals with results, analysis and dis- cussion. Based on the data we have, we have been able to show that the younger cohort manifests more education for spe- cific occupations than do the older cohorts. In other words, our data tend to support the credential inflation hypothesis. We have mixed, hence quite inconclusive, results in regard to the second hypothesis. We found that in some cases, there was more transfer of advantage from father to son in the younger than in the older generations. This was not necessarily so in some cases for transfer of advantage was much more apparent in the middle cohort. Similarly, we have mixed results with regard to intragenerational mobility. In some cases, educa- tion proved to be a more effective instrument for gaining high prestige occupations among the younger than in the older generations, while in other cases, education was more effec- tive in the middle cohort as a means to gaining privileged positions. We explained these mixed results in reference to effects of career stages and also historical background. We cannot clearly segregate the effects of career stages from that of historical period because of the nature of our data. This is a problem flowing from use of cohort analysis. Pempelani Oliver Mufune Zero-order correlations reveal that educational and occupa- tional achievements are becoming more associated over time. We conclude that occupational achievements are being affected not only by educational, nor for that matter occupational de- mands, but also changes in the economy and polity. Politics may be affecting occupational mobility in such a way as to produce no clear pattern of mobility. Whether there is demo- cratization or crystallization of opportunity may be a poli- tical question depending on political circumstances. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to express my sincere thanks to Professor David Wiley. Due to him I was able to Use data collected in surveys conducted under his direction in urban Zambia in l973. As chairman of my guidance committee Dr. Wiley has provided support. inspiration, expertise on the statistical analyses of the data and constructive criticism without which this thesis might never have been completed. I also extend thanks to Doctors William Faunce and Jay Artis for serving on my committee and for their questions, commentary and encourage- ment from which I have greatly benefitted. I Special thanks go to the African and Zambian community at Michigan State University as represented by Manenga and Maria Ndulo, David and Naomi Sibalwa, Lovejoy and Catherine Malambo, Mwizenge and Beth Tembo, Ken and Yvonne Mwanza, Saboi Sishimba, Pauline Peart, Mr..and Mrs. H. A. B. Msuku, and Peter Ngategize for their optimism and encouragement. Still in East Lansing I would like to thank Adreana Pringle for the informal discussions on models of social mobility and for the support she gave in transporting the material for typing. I should also thank Julia for providing excellent typing of the thesis in face of the deadlines. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE I INTRODUCTION ....................... 1 Literature Review ................... 2 Status attainment school: theoretical background, model ........................ 2 The opportunity school: the model .......... 5 The two schools contrasts and comparisons ....... 6 The emerging model .................. 6 Explaining the model: economic change and urbaniza- tion; urbanization, economic change and occupational structure; urbanization, economic change and the edu- cational system; economic change, class and family . . 10 II HISTORICAL BACKGROUND OF THE ZAMBIAN SITUATION AND COHORT FORMATION ........................ 18 Political pressure and the evolution of the educa-' tional system in Zambia ............... 18 Aspects of urbanization in Zambia .......... 20 The case for using cohort in studying social change. . 22 On the formation of our cohort groups ......... 23 Economic growth and the creation of wage employment in Zambia . ....................... 24 III PROBLEM SPECIFICATION AND METHODOLOGY ........... 31 Hypotheses ...................... 34 Data and Methodology ................. 37 IV RESULTS AND ANALYSIS AND DISCUSSION ............ 39 Characteristics of the Three City Male Random Sample . . .39 iii CHAPTER ’ PAGE Comparing fathers to sons ............... 42 Comparing Male Cohort Mean Educational Achievements - A Test of the Credential Inflation Hypotheses ...... 45 Behavioral Patterns of Educational and Occupational At- tainments: Testing Intergenerational and Intragenera- tional Privilege Transfer Hypotheses .......... 49 Intergenerational Status Transfers ....... t . . 53 Intragenerational (within career) status achievements . 59 Inter and within generation mobility based on Zero- order correlations .................. 63 Discussion and Conclusion ................ 65 APPENDICES ............................ 69 I On Prestige Scales of Occupations ............ 69 2 On Data and Methodology ................. 79 BIBLIOGRAPHY ........................... 83 iv TABLE OF ILLUSTRATIONS FIGURE PAGE A An Emerging Causal Model .................. 9 B Wage-Earning Africans in Employment, l921-l967, Inside and Outside Northern Rhodesia/Zambia .............. 28a C Path Models with Standardized Regression Coefficients of Educational and Occupational Status Inheritance from Fathers to Male Respondents and Hithin Respondents for all Age Cohorts in the Three City Random Sample, l973 ...... 5l D Path Model Utilizing Standardized Regression Coefficients of Educational and Occupational Status Inheritance from Fathers to Son and Within Sons Career in Three City Sample According to Age Cohort ........................ 52 TABLE l Zambian Urbanization l963-l974 ............... 21 2 Percentage Annual Growth Rate in Real Gross Domestic Pro- duct, Zambia 1965-76 .................... 27 3 The Ratio of Capital to Labor 1965 and l973 in Constant Kwacha', Zambia ...................... 29 4 Comparative Distribution of Education of all Employed Males Not Attending School Zambia, 1969, Compared with Male Education in the Three City Sample, l973 ....... 4O 5 Distribution of Employment Among Zambian Males in 1969 Census and in l973, Three City Random Sample ........ 4l 6 Education Achievement by Occupational Category in the Three City Sample, Male Respondents (l973) ......... 43 7 Educational Attainment of Fathers of our Male Respondents in Three City Sample by Occupational Category, l973 . . . . 44 8 Mean Years of Education Attained by Male Cohorts by Occu- pational Category in Three City Sample ........... 47 TABLE PAGE 9 Percentage of Cases Missing from Path Model ........ 54 TO Summary of Results Pertaining to Intergenerational Transfer of Privilege ........................ 57 ll Social Origin of the Male Respondents in Three City Sample by Age Cohorts ...................... 6la l2 Zero Order Correlations between Dimensions of Status- Attainment for the Three Zambian Age Cohorts (Older, Middle and Younger) l973 ..................... 64 13 Deviations in Prestige Rankings of Occupations of Males in Lusaka, Zambia and Combined SIOPS Inventory ........ 72 vi CHAPTER I Introduction This thesis is focused on aspects of social mobility in the rapid social change of Urban Zambia. He shall broadly consider structural and individual factors which affect the social economic positions of individ- uals. Social mobility refers to the movement of individuals from one-1eve1 to another within a society's system of social stratification. Conversely, social stratification can be conceptualized as a 'system of restricting access to positions of varying advantage' (Noble, 1974). Social mobility indicates the degree to which positions of advantage accrue to people at lower levels and conversely the ability of those at the top to maintain their positions. Sorokin's Social Mobility (1927) was the first classic on the topic. According to Nesolowski, et a1 (1979) Sorokin generated much discussion on the causes, processes and results of social mobility. Not until the 19505 were other works comparable to Sorokin's written. To this effect the writings of Rogoff (1953), Glass (1954). Carlson (1958), Lipset and Bendix (1959), Svalatoga (1959) and Miller (1960) are important. These built on Sorokin's research tradition but did not necessarily lead to new directions. Hesolowski, et a1 (1979) argue that by the late 1960's there was need to ground social mobility research in class/stratification theory. From this point of divergence developed two paradigms currently dominating mobility research. These are the 'status attainment school' and the 'opportunity school.‘ The status attainment model was fully ex- pressed in Blau and Duncan's The American Occupational Structure (1967). The aim of this group of researchers was to investigate determinants of individuals'social status, i.e. what accounts for the distribution of individuals among positions-n-a micro perspective. The opportunity model was fully expressed by Boudon in a book entitled, Education,_Opportunity and Social Inequality (1974). This group of researcher's aim is to answer the question-u-what accounts for the rate of mobility in society-u-a macro perspective. Literature Review The status attainment school Apart from Blau and Duncan other well known researchers in this school include Hauser (1969), Featherman (1974), Treiman (1977), and Sewell (1975). Apart from Sewell who had worked in this area before, the work of most others can be said to be building upon Blau and Duncan's origina1*work. Theoretical background of status attainment literature Burawoy (1977) and Coser (1975), among others have alluded to the atheoretical nature of status attainment literature, an assertion which Horan (1978), Qvortrup (1979), Crowder (1974) believe is a misconception. These have strived to go beyond mere critiques of status attainment research to demonstrate that the criticized aspects have their roots, to use Horan's phrase, in their 'theoretically laden nature'-n-i.e. in the functionalism of Davis and Moore (1945) and Parsons (1949, 1953). The paper by Davis and Moore (1945) was one of the most articulate among functionalist writings on social stratification. Over the years it has elicited a great deal of discussion, and this presentation of it is quite simplified. For Davis and Moore each society has social stratification. Every society has ranked social positions differentiated with rewards and status in terms of their functional importance. These rewards are given for estimations of the contributions to society by role occupants. The posi- tions can be described as having 'unequal functional importance' (Buckley 1963). How are the differentially ranked social positions assigned? Davis and Moore (1945) assume the existence in society of an unequal supply of talent. The eufunctioning of the system requires that the most qualified members of society fill positions with higher requirements of skill and knowledge. The theory assumes higher prestige positions require higher levels of skill and knowledge. Thus the occupants of different positions are given unequal rewards so as to motivate them. The operative principle is, 'from each according to his ability and to each according to his contribution' (Tausky 1963). For Davis and Moore (1945) stratification is the system of unequal rewards attached to different social positions in a society. The system is functional in that positions are deemed more important if they contribute more to society's adaptability and survival. Accordingly these positions are more highly rewarded. Differences in stratification between different societies, Davis and Moore maintain, stem from the mode of filling the important positions and their definition. Talcott Parsons (1940, 1953) is largely consonant with Davis and Moore's (1945) account of stratification. Stratification is universal and neces- sary; however, he lays emphasis on a 'common value system.‘ He views stratification then as the 'ranking of individuals in a social system in accordance with the standards of a common value system' (Gouldner 1970). He places this in his scheme of pattern variables emphasizing differences in the openness and modernity of different societies. Researchers in status attainment have been said to be in the func- tionalist tradition by Horan (1978), Quortrup (1979) and Crowder (1974). Thus, they have been said to distinguish between open and closed societies with the former characterized by universalist, specific and affective neu- tral roles. They have been said to work in a specific value system of liberalism, individualism and private property (Horan 1978, p. 538, Quortrup 1979, p. 275, Crowder 1974, p. 39). This leads status attainment research, the argument goes, to place emphasis on individual and also an insistence on equality of opportunity rather than of conditions. The opponents of status attainment research may have overstated their case. Social mobility must face two different questions: what ac- counts for the rate of mobility and what accounts for the distribution of individuals among positions. It so happens that status attainment researCh- ers are preoccupied with individual rather than with structure because they concern themselves with the latter question. Measures of individual behavior and belief do not necessarily presuppose a functionalist position. Indi- vidual researchers may be close to or may share some common assumptions with functionalist stratification theory but this does not mean that all status attainment research is grounded in functionalism. The model Status attainment researchers focus on a set of intervening vari- ables in order to explain the transition from status origin to destination. Thus, 'a person starts life and spends the early part of it in a family, acquires education, translates this eduCation into an occupation which in turn gives him an income and status.‘ These life cycles occur in more or less temporal order in which factors at each prior stage influence those at the next (Crowder 1974, Duncan 1969). As Haller and Portes (l973) show,the Blau and Duncan model of status attainment aims at reconceptual- izing classic questions of mobility by use of a more analytic model. They want to gauge how far the social fate of individuals depends on the status they inherit and how far later career achievements depend on earlier ones. Thus the model employs objective status variables to investigate the process whereby status is transmitted. The opportunity school On the basis of the various criticisms of the status attainment researchers and their neglect to account for the rate of mobility,a separate school has developed which Sorenson (1976) has labelled the 'opportunity school.‘ Researchers here aim at determining the degree to which patterns and amounts of social mobility depend on the larger social structures and social change in society (Hesolowski et a1 1979). Their concern is with mechanisms of social processes lying behind observed causal processes for occupational attainment (Sorensen 1976). The stratification theory of the opportunity school is more eclectic. Boudon (1974) himself approvingly quotes Dahrendorf to the effect that, present social stratification theory is an 'Oedus 1and,‘ i.e. a desert. because, although there is a mass of writings, there exist no satisfactory stratification theory concerning industrial society; however, Boudon himself seems to share, 'an elective affinity to certain non-dogmatic neo-marxian literature' (Alker 1976). The opportunity school model Researchers in the opportunity school assume there exists in society unequal status as 'created' (processed) by the family through socialization and unequal access to educational opportunity (IEO). It is also assumed that inequalities in social opportunity (ISO) exist along- side meritocratic principles and values which serve legitimation purposes. The issue then is how far do achievement patterns conform to the merit- ocratic principle and how far do children replicate their parents' social status. In the opportunity model, endogenous and exogenous mechanisms responsible for inequality are distinguished. Endogenous mechanisms are reflected in choices related to individual desires and decisions emanating from the processes of socialization and selection which are internalized by individuals. For example, one chooses to enter school provided he or she is qualified. Exogenous mechanisms do not present much choice to the individual. They refer to actions limited or fixed by political, technological and/or organizational forces. For example, a job does not exist just because an individual wants to fill it. These researchers utilize endogenous mechansims producing IEO, transmitting it into ISO, so as to explain the direction and amount of mobility over time in the context of existing exogenous mechanisms. The two schools The stressed differences between researchers in the status-attainment and in the opportunity school tradition have mainly been ideological. As Rogoff (1976) notes,the two schools have common ground and converge in important respects: i. They both describe mobility in a temporal framework focus- ing on calendar time and/or life cycle. Thus, in both the concern is with tracing successive cohort status. ii. A major idea behind both is Noble's (1974) conception of stratification, in part, as 'the restriction of access to positions of varying advantage.‘ This leads them to look at mechanisms of restriction versus mechanisms of freedom affecting individuals. For those in the opportunity school, this is expressed as meritocracy versus domination, for the others as ascription versus achievement. iii. Both are concerned with initial role allocation. The main consideration rests with the family and school which are considered as determinant of the period around adolescence which in turn sets the stage on which positions are gained or lost. iv. The differences between status attainment and opportunity school researchers surface regarding solutions to problems related to blocked mobility, i.e. at the level of resource distribution. When the task defined is to analyze social change and mobility, then both schools have much to offer, for they are not mutually exclusive. It is possible to derive a causal model from both schools which is help- ful in explaining the social mobility of individuals in a rapidly changing social situation. Moreover the two schools are based on an unsound con- ception of the division between micro and macro sociology arising from the argument in theory as to what is the nature of the relationship be- tween individual and society: that is asking as to whether one or the other has dominant effects, i.e. is society primary while personality is derivative or vice versa? Our approach here is similar to Berger and Luckmann (1967) where society is conceived of as both an objective and subjective reality, where the relationship between individual and objective reality is like an 'ongoing balancing act' and therefore in a situation of dynamic if not dialectical interaction. nsnunnnnnat- muometm xgmucouwm maumwem crux -u-------u---------tut---u-u--u----u--uumuuuuuuuuuutmuutunuulnu-u-utuuuuuuulnutunutuuuunuuuuuuu-u-------- mp peeve; no.» Ptum< oucmuwmmm xuwcsssoo m~pm xpvsma lvi 5:83 5%“. T. :orumazuuo mucosa; :o'pmuaum mucoema scrawlxww5mu <.-_----------------- noom\_mwtamzucm . new 53323.5 T smumam $8.5 -mcgmpcm . e»: mmwuppoa % 28.538 Fm_copou . lumoa new mmvuvpvuou copautmwz wnmsmwmwuw< .copuouaeu .m.m .mmp» maummtm vacopou F p» o -vcauioaao mewumrxm copuuu a to on: upmaup>vccfi u------------tuunu-- upwwumtam 57 ace mmmpu . - u a n u . . L n m mampmzm T s” n 3838:: ml “ m pmcopumaauoo n u u u m m < " moccasu oveoc . u . . . . . . . . bravucwta aumguoawtmz pone: panama mcpmtmsu =< < maze“; lO Explaining the model The central focus of the model is on capacity of individuals to use existing structures and opportunities in 'gaining and losing' social economic position. The basic question is -- does the changing character of societal structures imply an increase or decrease in individuals ex- perience of mobility? An individual's position is largely conditioned by his capacity (socially inherited and acquired) to react to changing levels of urbanization (alterations in rural - urban ratios); industri- alization (economic changes adding to formal industrial employment) and their complex interaction with class structures which affect and are affected by occupational, educational and family syStems. We assume societies differ in their stress on the principles of merit and ascription. Meritocracy relates to equality of opportunity rather than of conditions (i.e. of wealth and power). Ideally, for instance, in a system of unequal conditions an education system can exist in which the talented are selected and promoted on the basis of their performance and other universalistic criteria. The ascription principle implies no use of universalistic criteria. In practice the distinction between the two principles is much more complex. Universal- istic criteria like education can themselves imply ascription. Thus po- sitions are gained on the basis of school certificates which are taken to be indicators of skill and knowledge on the job, but this may not neces- sarily be the case. In Africa education becomes justification for privilege legitimized on the basis of "need for development." For simplicity's sakelwe see meritocracy as more apparent in a situation where one's position depends 11 on achievements in the educational and occupational systems regardless of family background. Conversely ascription is more apparent where one‘s family exerts more influence in gaining position. However, we keep in mind’that every system is a mixture of meritocracy and ascription. Economic change and urbanization By urbanization we mean increases in the proportion of people liv- ing in urban areas, and this can be a consequence both of migration and of internal growth in towns themselves. By economic change, we mean changes in the organization, production and technological levels of industry. This can entail a movement from a domestic economy to small scale manufacture to larger scale industry. This can imply need for an expanded labor sup- ply and market. Thus, ideally towns are suitable for industry. This led Balan et a1 (1973) to say 'there is no known case of large scale industrial change with no concomitant urbanization.‘ However, the two can occur separately. Using mining as an example of a town forming factor in Africa, Lisowski (1978) reviewed literature pertaining to the relationship be- tween industrialization and urbanization. He found that mines in them- selves do not make cities but have been vital in their coming up in some tropical African countries. Over 10% of towns in tropical Africa owe their origins to mining. The share of mining towns of over 10,000 people are -- for Zambia 56%, Zimbabwe 50%, Liberia 25%, Sierra-Leone 25%, and Zaire 14% (Lisowski 1978). Mining gave impetus to urbanization but the relationship between the two has been limited. Thus where mining demand for labor does not grow fast, stagnates or drops, it is observed that urbanization then outpaces industry. For this to happen, original rural 12 societies have to be greatly altered. Lisowski (1978) argues that in situations where rural societies are intact is has been observed that lessened mining industrial activity leads to less urbanization. Thus, some mining settlements of 10,000 people before 1950 declined. This was the case with Kilomines in Zaire, Aboso in Ghana, Bindura and Sinoia in ' Zimbabwe. Bibian, in Ghana, has similarly experienced a drop from 13,000 people in 1967 to 9,700 in 1970. In tropical Africa then mining indus- trial developments seem to have a close relation to urbanization which seems to be influenced by regionally, specific historical circumstances. This is especially so for Zambia which mining has made the most urbanized nation in black Africa. Urbanization, economic change and occupational structure Industry and town seem to be consequential for the occupational system. Hilbert Moore (1969) conceptualizes this in terms of increased division of labor, noting an increase in the size of economic organiza- tions allowing for more specialization. He also notes technological changes creating entirely new occupations and novel services and products cre- ating hitherto non-existent occupations (Faunce and Form 1969). Indus- trial change implies changes within the economy such as an increase in percentage of labor in industry relative to agriculture. It also implies a shift in the concentration of labor from primary to secondary to ter- tiary sectors of the economy. An increase in the use of machines in the labor process may in some sectors create skilled as distinct from unskilled and semi-skilled labor but sometimes breaks up skills (e.g. craft) into semi-skilled jobs. The relationship between skilled labor and mechanization then seems to be very complex depending on circumstances, 13 technology, etc. (Marx 1977). 'There have been investigations of some of the above statements in the Third World. Farooq (1973) investigated changes in the labor force with changes in industrial levels for west and east Pakistan in the decade 1951 - 1961. He found that although agriculture still predominated there was a tendency for its decrease especially in the west where the rate of industrial change was higher. The west had 4.5% per annum growth of nonfarm employment and a 6% increase in the pro- portion of nonagriculture labor force. There were also changes towards rising industrial skills and productivity with increased industrial activity. Joseph Ramos (1970) found that for Latin-America-the quality of the labor force changed with increased industrial activity. There was an increase in the average number of years of schooling for workers. Hazel Moir (1977) did a time series study relating labor force structure urbanization and development. She found that for Third World, the ratio of urbanization and the percentage share of the labor force in nonagri- culture neither affects nor is affected by increase of industrial activity. In Africa most studies on changes in the labor force in economic develop- ment have focused on stabilization -- i.e., whether there has been a commitment to wage labor employment by the people. This commitment to wage labor is important for mobility because it is only such a labor force which can collectively and individually seek mobility opportunities, improvement in skills and education. For Zambia,Mitchell (1961),Heissler (1974) and Baldwin (1966) have argued labor stabilization has occurred with increased industrial activity. l4 Urbanization, economic change and the education system There seensto be a close reciprocal relation between industry and education. Hith industrial activity increase, education is no longer for socializing individuals in traditional philosophy, religion, classics or law but stress is laid on natural science, medicine, etc. (Kerr, et al 1969). with the movement from small scale to large scale industry there seems to be a dialectical pull towards both specialization and generalization. Specialization is needed to develop professionals, technicians, and managers. 0n the other hand, in a rapidly changing situation there is an increase in knowledge making for difficulties in specialization. Individuals perceive 'benefits' of education and thus demand its increase. Industry stimulates demand for education and skill, on the other hand, industries have educational subsystems like apprenticeships. Thus there is a reciprocal relation. The above seem to be the case for Africa. The whole social economic system is closely related to the distribution and provision of opportunity and education. Soja (1968) and Gould (1970) looking at Kenya and Uganda found that location of schools were greatly affected by spread effects such as the distribution of population and backwash effects such as economic development. In many rural areas the population is dispersed, hence politically weak, making it difficult to establish schools and so educational opportunities are denied. In urban areas the higher population density makes it easier to establish cheaper day, as against boarding schools. In Ghana the distribution of schools was. said by Hunter to reflect differences in wealth (quoted in Gould 1970). Clignet (1966) holds the‘same position for Ivory Coast and so does Forster (1968) 15 for Senegal. Most studies then suggest that urban areas in Africa have more opportunities because they are richer, have greater awareness of educational benefits and, above all, are relatively politically strong. The provision of education to them is a way of appeasing real or poten- tial political opposition. This seems to constitute and determine the demand and supply of education. As Bowles (1978) notes this can have unintended consequences of producing 'credential inflation' i.e. a contradiction where school system produces more graduates than there are jobs in capitalist mode leading to escalated qualification for jobs in turn leading to frustrated expectations and demand for access to next educational level and so on. Economic change, class and family The family is not impervious to changes in modes of work, life expectancies, migration, loss of functions to schools, factories, etc. associated with urbanization and economic change. For developed countries researchers say parental authority has been weakened whereas strong- kinship relations only remain in the nuclear family -- a specialized unit of emotional gratification (Parker et a1). Lloyd (1967) argues that in Africa there are growing differences in socialization of children between classes. Specifically citing Nigeria, he says elites know how to manipu- late the educational system. They employ tutors to teach their children and through their influence put their children in higher or better schools. Elite child socialization places emphasis on the realization of potential abilities and thus is more tolerant of aggressive behavior in play. Non- elites emphasize cooperation. Radical theorists such as Batzel (1958) 16 and Domhoff (1970) have argued that the family reproduces existing patterns of inequalities in society by influencing individual aspirations, ambition and provision of the means for translating ambitions into opportunities without challenging opportunity structures themselves. In summary we can say that a review of research pertaining to in- vestigated relationships between urbanization, economic changes, family, class, occupation and educational systems leads to/or reveals conceptions embodied in our model (Figure A). The relationships are complex and con- jectural but embody a conception tying together structures of society, structures of reward and opportunity, and individuals and family units. Basic to our model (Figure A) is the conception that the structures of society, both structures of opportunity and structures of reward, exist .2519; to the individual and the family unit. These structures are largely determined by the given, but sometimes changing, system of social stratifi- cation in the society. This system reflects the underlying system of power and authority of the "preceding historical period," from which emerges a mixed system of rewards and sanctions for individuals. Rewards nay be allocated for quality performance, but access to the ability to learn (socialization and education) those performances are unequally. distributed across the class system. Throughout the system also exist sanctions for "performance failures;" however, there also are various amounts of leniency and "forgiveness" according to the nature of the class position of the actor and the nature of the task and organization in which the occupational role of the actor is located. Social mobility, therefore, is conceived as the process by which in- dividuals from unequal social origins obtain unequal levels of preparation l7 (socialization and education) and then unequal attainment of occupational level. The occupational system, however, also is changing according to a) the nature of the economic state of the world system, b) the supply and demand for the materials, goods, and serviCes produced in a state, c) the supply of more and less skilled workers, d) the competing occupa- tional systems in neighboring states, and e) the policy of the state in the allocating of rewards to workers in various industries, sectors, and occupational levels, indeed, even to particular occupational roles. It is difficult in any occupational system to obtain a good sampling of the major attributes of the éystgm. One alternative to sampling the major social forces which shape the system is to sample the experience of workers moving through the system. Workers entering at different times in history experience different rates and types of mobility, rewards and sanctions for performances, and arrive with various levels of sociali- zation and education for those occupational roles. One method of segregating the nature of the differences in the occupational structure at different periods of history is to observe the gross levels of mobility occurring at any given time in the system and to associate those levels with the observed rates and directions of occupa- tional and economic mobility of the workers in the system. CHAPTER II On the Historical Background of Zambian Situation and Specification of the Cohorts Political pressure and the evolution of the educational system in Zambia Three broad levels of education can be identified in Zambia. The first is the primary stage consisting of 7 (previously 8) years of educa- tion. The secondary stage consisting of 5 years (previously 6) of educa- ' tion, and post-secondary stage consists of teacher, technical and nursing training colleges, and the university. At independence in 1964 the country of about 4 million had less than 1,000 citizens with a high school cer- tificate and less than 100 had completed a university degree. Thus post primary education was quite underdeveloped (Elliot 1975, Coombe 1967, G.R.Z. 1969). Primary education was different. As early as around 1884 Anort, a French missionary, had started a school in the Western Province. By 1937 primary education had been spread by missionaries until nearly 30,000 pupils were enrolled. By the 19405 over 100,000 pupils had been enrolled in government-funded schools. By 1963 at least 64% and 45% of the eligible boys and girls respectively had been enrolled in primary schools. This at least compared favorably with other colonies. In con- trast secondary schools were started in 1938 at Munali with 11 students, 54 years later than primary school. As late as 1952 there were only 405 Africans in secondary schools. This meant about one place in secondary 18 19 school for 350 places in primary school (Sanyal 1976). The reasons for this sorry state of affairs are complex and debatable. Elliot (1975) blames the great depression after 1930 for this, but the depression can- not explain why settler and primary education were not affected, nor why other colonial countries were not affected similarly. The main reason seems to be political. First, African education was designed to be elementary for curbing illiteracy and not for political awareness (Coombe 1967). Secondly, education was racially segregated. The set- tlers had the privileges. Koloko (1980) says, 'the colonial government earmarked £3,893,700 for the education of 10,000 Europeans but only £86,000 for the 3.5 million Africans in the 1951 ten year development plan. Settlers opposed African education on the ground of avoiding compe- tition for jobs, and this was the greatest political obstacle to African educational advancement (Coombe 1968). The colonial situation gave birth to two factors important for education in the post-colonial era. The first was the link between political oppression and educational backward- ness. The second was that education was seen as a prerequisite for ad- vancement in employment. It is in this context that education became a central issue in the 1962 elections and the fight against the federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland. After independence the government of Zambia believed that the pro- vision of education was the surest way of equitably sharing the fruits of the struggle and a way of appeasing hitherto politically excluded groups. Post-colonial educational developments have been impressive. Primary education has continued to expand with the result that by 1970 almost 90% of those eligible to attend primary class were at school, an increase of 20 approximately 50% from the 1963 figure. In comparison to other developing countries, percentage yearly increases in primary and secondary school en- rollment have been impressively high. Linear expansion of secondary schools has quadrupled enrollments in less than a decade of independence since 1964. Expansion at secondary school level has been the most rapid in Africa (Elliot, J. 1975), but this educational expansion at one level may have meant more intense competition for access to another level. According to Stannard (1971) during the 1970-75 period 345,000 primary school leavers could not obtain places at secondary schools, and there were to be an additional 142,000 dropouts at other grades (quoted in Elliot, J. 1975). The university also experienced a rapid development. It was opened in 1966 with 312 students. By 1970 it had an enrollment of 1,184. Average annual rate of enrollment increase was about 40%. This slowed to about 22% in the period 1970-74, making for a 30% annual rate of increase between 1966 and 1974. A number of teacher and technical training institu- tions have been opened since independence. Thus, formal education spread widely after independence and hence made the situation especially suitable for testing the credential inflation hypothesis. Aspects of urbanization in Zambia The ratio of the urban to rural population was relatively high in colonial Zambia, due primarily to the mining industry. Although at in- dependence the country with 19% of the population in towns, was recog- nized as the most urbanized south of the Sahara, the increase of urbanites was somewhat gradual,mostly because of governmental controls. To be an urban resident one had to carry an identity card specifying one as such. Most of the urban residents came to seek gainful employment. Meanwhile 21 income differentials were wide. Urban per-capital income as K291 (K1=$1.25) while for rural areas it was K23 (Simmance 1975, Seers report 1964). This worsened with independence when between 1964-69 urban real income rose by 50%. The terms of trade worsened against rural areas, thus the real purchasing power of a unit of marketed peasant output fell by 20% from 1964 to 1973 (Fry and Maimbo 1973). Rural agriculture was neglected with the effect of pushing the food import bill higher. These growing rural-urban inequalities led to unprecedented rural urban migration. TABLE 1 Zambian Urbanization 1963-1974 , Urban Rural Total Percentage Year Population Population of Population, Urban 1963 667,000 2,843,000 19 % 1969 1,128,000 2,971,000 27.5% 1971 1,309,000 3,027,000 30.2% 1974 1,700,000 3,030,000 35.3% From Simmance (1975) and Mwanza (1979). These urbanization figures have the implication of increasing pres- sure on existing socioeconomic opportunities in urban areas. To gain access to formal industrial employment and indeed to higher levels of education requires one to have a competitive edge, and in such a situation it is our expectation that parents with initial advantages of education, high occupation, and wealth will be more successful in providing their 22 dependents with this competitive edge. The case for using cohorisin studying social change Support for use of cohort analysis in studying social change comes from both Marxist and non-Marxist writers. In the 'German Ideology' Marx (1965, p. 57) states, 'history is nothing but the succession of the sepa- rate generations, each of which exploits the materials, capital funds, the productive forces handed down to it by all preceding generations, and thus on the one hand, continues the traditional activity in completely changed circumstances and on the other, modifies the old circumstances with a completely changed activity.‘ Three non-Marxist sociologists have argued for use of cohorisin social change analysis. These are Ryder (1965); Carlsson and Karlsson (l970),Hagenaars and Cobben (1978). These have argued that the use of cohortsrests on the observed tendency in social psychology that with in- creasing age individuals are less likely to change. Carlsson et a1 (1970) report studies showing that 'learning ability' declines with age, especially with regard to tests of reasoning and nonverbal materials. They also report studies by Chown (1960) showing that flexibility (inno- vativeness) to intellectually grasp new behavior lessens with age. As one gets older, he is more experienced in his work; however, one benefits increasingly less from knowledge and skills acquired in the training phases (Hagenaars 1978). Ryder (1965) talks of the 'intersection of innovative and conservative forces in history' in which every cohort group has a fresh start with the social heritage it finds. Cohort refers to 'a set of individuals who pass some crucial stage or experience a fundamental event like marriage, first job and especially 23 birth at approximately the same time' (Carlsson et a1 1970). A cohort can be taken to be a bearer of an imprint of given events which it ex- perienced around a particular age and which left a lasting mark on it (Hagenaars et al 1978). Our focus is on birth cohorts for age is not only a 'rubric of consequences of people's actions but also a basis for allocating roles in society' (Ryder 1965). With regard to employment and labor force participation specific age cohorts will differ according to the character of the labor market they meet upon entry. The case is similar with regard to education. This is important in this study which focuses on occupational mobility. On the Formation of the Cohort Groups We have divided the sample into three (3) cohort categories. The first category consists of those who were 18 to 29 years of age. These total 322 respondents and form 36.4% of our male random sample. The middle cohort category consists of those from 30 to 39 years of age. These total 283 respondents and form 32.0% of our male random sample. The oldest co- hort consists of those with 40 years of age and beyond. These total 279 respondents and constitute 31.6% of our male random sample. The cohort categories are not formed in an arbitrary manner, rather they are deliberately made to reflect the historical character of the Zambian occupational structure when the respondents in the three categories entered the labor market. The cohorts are formed so as to reflect rela- tively homogenous aggregates for the historical character of the labor force at the time the respondents in the three categories were entering the labor market. We estimate that respondents in the older cohort entered 24 the labor force in the years prior to 1949, those in the middle cohort in the years from the early 19505 to the early 19605, and those in the‘ younger cohort entered the paid labor force in the years after 1963/1964. The labor market for the older cohort was based on state and mining activity. The labor market of the middle cohort had experienced an added expansion due to colonial development plans starting around 1948 with pressures from trade unions and the movement for political independence. The younger co- hort met labor force conditions affected by political change (independence) and which are one of rapid expansion based on greater revenues due to unprecedented demand for copper, favorable tax reforms (especially ex- propriation of the British South Africa mineral rights) and a more or less conscious policy to enlarge the wage labor force in order to fulfill pre- independence political promises. We turn to description of these three his- torical periods which form the basis for our cohort formation as shown in Table 14 in Appendix 11. 'Economic growth and the creation of wage employment in Zambia' For analytical purposes we conceptualize three phases in the economic growth of Zambia from the period 1920 to 1974 which define the cohorts. The first one is mostly based on administrative and mining activity. This started with the prospecting around the 19005 and continued up to the 19305. We identify the second period of economic growth with the colonial government's development plans, with their emphasis on some economic diversification. The third period of economic growth is identified with the post-colonial government and its relatively more intense efforts at diversification -- especially in the area of manufacturing. 25 First phase of the economy During this time (1900-1940) whatever economic development took place was principally in mining. The developments are shown in figures compiled by Coleman (1969) from government and mining statistical reports. Copper production itself was well underway by 1908 when about 589 long tons were realized. This continued with the high mark of 1912 when 1,972 tons were produced. Then there was a drop in production with a bottom of 96 tons in 1918 because of the World War I. Up to 1926 production largely remained approximately at several hundred tons. From 1927 to the early 19305 the production figure averaged several thousand tons. This changed with the adoption of large scale mining methods stimulated by high prices due to rearmament and'new techniques of processing lower grade ore. This encouraged the opening of several other mines, dramatically enlarging production. In 1933, 103,516 long tons were produced and this steadily rose to the figure of 228,254 by 1941. During this period wage employment closely paralleled mining developments. Thus during the depression many wage earners were laid off. With the end of the depression, production picked up absorbing larger quantities of labor and lessening the number of Zambians employed outside the country as shown in Figure 8. Second phase of the economy This period started around 1948 when there was unprecedented demand for copper and a sharp rise in its production. Production rose from 77.2 long tons in 1947 to 130.6 in 1948 to 220.7 by 1951. The colonial government realized that substantial profits were being realized by mining companies. The authorities faced with pressure from the settler community and rising African expectations and demands, as reflected in trade union 26 and political party movements, was pressed to devote some efforts towards other areas of the economy. The authorities wrested more revenue from the mining companies. Whereas in 1947 the companies provided only 27.7% of government revenues in 1948 they provided about 44.9% of its revenue, and 57.5% by 1952 (Berger, E. 1974, p. 8). According to Berger (1974), the companies were even a greater source of government revenue than income tax payments indicate. It is in this context that the first development plan of 1948 was launched. Its primary aims were to increase food production and construction (road and housing) activities. According to Sanyal et a1 (1975) the plan actually used£80.5 million to increase and upgrade communication networks and housing. Agricultural output increased more than 10 fold, as did copper production which increased 8 fold, and African education whose expenditure increased 20 fold. With regard to manufacturing Thompson (1957) and Baldwin (1966) note that the colonial development corporation was set up. In its report this corporation said manufacturing was not feasible till the Europeans reached 35,000 and the internal African market was enlarged. Despite this, however, a cement factory, hydroelectric project at Kariba, sawmill and furniture industry, and beverage and clothing industries were estab- lished. In 1950 the loans board was set up to help small scale manufac- turing efforts. Wage employment in construction itself increased from 60,000 to 180,000 (Baldwin 1966). Thus, the colonial plan had an impact in wage labor creation. It is actually the cause of the rise starting at the end of the 19405 as shown in Figure B. 27 Third phase of the economy The next spurt of growth consequential for increase in wage employ- ment came with political independence. It must be mentioned that the colonial governments efforts in manufacturing were minimal. The Seers report (1964) declared that 'for the level of income and population size, the manufacturing sector of the economy was unusually backward.’ The major reason for this seem to have been the country's economic inte- gration with Zimbabwe (then Southern Rhodesia) and South Africa -- especially during the Federation of Rhodesia and‘Nyasaland -- in which Zambia was a market. This could not continue after political independence. The country had to partially disengage from being a periphery of the south. This started by seeking alternative sea routes, improvement of communica- tions, and, most important, local manufacture. After 1964, manufacture experienced a dramatic growth rate. Whereas it constituted 6.1% of the G.D.P. in 1964 it was 13.5% in 1972 (Steen 1975). From 1964 to 1974 many enterprises were founded. Among these were shoe, cement, rubber, explosive, glass, chemical, metallic, oil refining, engineering, and auto assembly enterprises. Table 2 below provides a picture of the unprecedented spurt of growth in various sectors of the economy: TABLE 2 Percentage annual growth rate in real Gross Domestic Product, Zambia 1965-76 Sector 1965-70 1970-76 1965-76 Agriculture 7.6 10.1 8.6 Mining -4.8 0.3 -2.0 Manufacturing 11.2 4.8 7.7 28 TABLE 2 (cont'd.) Sector 1965-70 1970-76 1965-76 Construction -2.4 4.5 1.4 Transport 2.2 1.1 1.8 Services 9.3 4.5 6.7 From Mwanza, J. (1979). This growth was possible because of the high copper prices on the world market and the post-colonial regimes plans which were a response to popular pressure. This spurt of growth explains the sharp rise in wage employment starting from around 1964 (see Figure 8). According to Mwanza (1979), between 1969 and 1974 wage employment increased by 12.2%. The annual increase was 5.1% from 1965-70 and 1.4% from 1970-74. After 1974, however, there has been a loss of growth in wage employment. Even before that,the 1.4% growth of 1970-74 could not absorb the people who were leaving school and therefore looking for jobs. Our age cohorts are formed from and so as to reflect the three labor market phases we have described. The oldest cohort consists of workers who entered the labor market during the first phase, the middle cohort during the colonial plan phase, while the youngest reflect the post- colonial labor market as figure 8 indicates. There are problems encountered in the use of cohorts in analyzing aspects of social change, and we see at least three shortcomings. First, all three cohorts share the effects of recent history. It is not possible to segregate out the unique experiences of each from the specific effects shared by all three cohorts. Second, there are historically constituted differences of the meaning of such A.aouaav -E—lfifl am: £3 am: 2.: was _ .oo.o~ ........ \11/ . \ . .3..- Eofiuon 033.6 nacho—elm 08.3. Aakap ..La_v . .a .»o__: Aqua-sue coo so“ 3.: 3222 3.323 32.302 03.5 :0ng .u 2 coa.oo~ , a MoOZULO‘OU o oooNoOIUHzoo-o ooooooooooooo.odoO.“H°‘°0..‘ . ccodcn .naa-au\au..ooau auqsu soo~.a~a~ .uaanuodaua a. no: .u«.u=o an. .oa can accouuud manhunt-cu: I can»: ocmLocn 29 variables as education. Third, the time (distance) between first and current job status in path model we are going to use differ for the three cohort groups and hence are not fully comparable. The older cohort has longer career time since the first job than the middle and younger cohorts. This makes it difficult to segregate.out the separate effects of career stage and age from historical period. It is important to note that the creation of employment over the years is important to our hypotheses, because the cost of creating a single job as measured by the capital-labor ratio has been rising over the years. This may or may not affect level of skills in occupations. TABLE 3 The Ratio of Capital to Labor 1965 and 1973 in Constant Kwacha', Zambia (Amount of Kwacha needed to create one job by occupational sector) Sector 1965 1973 Commercial Agriculture K 826.5 K 2,914.0 Mining 9,970.0 10,747.0 Transport 8,955.0 10,454.0 Construction 336.0 783.0 Manufacturing 944.0 3,658.0 Services 6,213.0 8,037.0 Total - K4,54l.O K 6,099.0 From Mwanza, J. (1979). As Table 3 shows, capital-labor ratio rose from around K4,54l.0 to K6,099.0 from 1965 to 1973. The increase is approximately 35% in real 3O terms. As Mwanza (1979) maintains, the implication is that it cost 35% more in resources in creating a single job in 1973 than it did in 1965. This same cost had been increasing before 1965. The argument which relates to our hypotheses is that as the resource outlay for creating a job rises so should the outlay of resources a given individual dispenses with in order to fill that job. The cost of job creation increase actually reflects increases in mechanization and capital intensity. The implication might be that in order to perform the roles associated with these jobs adequately one requires more education and skills and that is assuming changes in nature of tasks. In this case we would expect those with initial advantages to be more successful in gaining access to these occupations. However, the relationship between mechanization (or capital intensity) is not a simple linear one. It is ‘ sometimes curvi-linear or much more complex. Thus mechanization may lead to deskilling like in the case of break up of high skill craft industries and the creation of low skill wage labor. On the other hand, in some sectors like in refining the requirements for maintenance may make for a demand in high skill labor. It is difficult to segregate the effects of mechanization on skill in our case. CHAPTER III Problem Specification and Methodology Our basic question is -i do changing societal and economic states. of structures imply an increase or decrease in the individuals experience of mobility. Through use of cohort analysis we want to answer these questions (which we shall translate into hypotheses): How are the rates and patterns of mobility among individuals in our cohort samples being affected by socioeconomic changes? How do changing occupational and educational systems affect the mobility of individuals? These questions reflect the argument between those who conceptualize a process of democratization of access to opportunities and those who per- ceive a process of crystallization or reproduction of structured inequality. Robinson (1978) argues mobility in the Third World is easier because as countries industrialize there is a movement into industrial classes, it requires lessor resource outlay for individuals to change position and there is relatively little institutionalization implying less obstacles to mobility across lines. This assumes an expanding economy,.and since there are periods of crisis and booms, it is time specific. With economic expansion structural inequality is lessened. Peil (1965) in- vestigated Ghanaian students and compared her results to Jahodas (1954) study. She found that during the decade between the two studies, ethnic: and social bases of recruitment of students had broadened to a wider range. 31 32 Currie (1975) compared student bodies of secondary schools for the years 1954, 1959, 1964 and 1969 in Uganda. She found a greater democratization of education access in terms of ethnic” and geographic origin over the whole period (quoted in Forster 1980). Van den Berghe and Nuttney compared students at Ibadan University in Nigeria in 1948 and 1968. They found lessening structural inequalities and greater democratization of access. The class crystallization argument states that inequalities are re- produced with social changes. 'The rulers of almost every country have wished industrialization to augment either their own power or the dominance of the social class they represent' (Sutcliffe 1971). Bowles and Ginti's have argued the primary function of education has been to reproduce (i.e. strengthen) the same division of labor functional to capitalism, i.e. reinforce inferior positions of the underprivileged and Cicourel and Kitsuse argue the same position (Weis, 1979). Weis (1979) tested these propositions using Ghanian data by comparing students in 1961 and 1974. The 1961 data had been collected by Forster who found high selectivity differentials. A child of a professional or clerical worker had 60% and 11% more chances of getting into secondary school than that of skilled workers or farmers respectively. In 1961 there were only 14,000 students in 39 public schools, whereas in 1974 there were 56,800 in 139 schools. Weis used fathers occupation as an indicator of social backgrounds. She concludes that if recruitment was not fluid in 1961 it was very much less so in 1974. Whereas in 1961 2% of males and 7% of females had professional fathers the figure had shot up to over 13% for both in 1974. Whereas 19% males and 25% females came from clerical families in 1961 these were respectively 5% and 9% in 1974. Weis concludes 33 that the expansion of education implies increased reproduction (i.e. reinforcement) of social inequality. Chaim Adler (1974) investigated the influence of educational expansion on ethnic student recruitment and attainment in Israel and found that the gap in recruitment and achievements between Jews of oriental, European and American origin had increased in favor of the latter groups. Olson (1972) found a similar case for Kenya. Despite educational expansion between 1961 and 1968 the representation of youth from fathers with no schooling in- creased from 0.4% to 0.5% while those from fathers with elementary educa- tion slightly fell, thereby indicating no substantively significant changes. In contrast youth with fathers having some secondary education experienced marked improvement into access to secondary schools. Van den Berghe found similar results in 1968 when he compared his to Goldthorpes 1958 data for Makerere students (Uganda). He concludes that there is a gradual process of elite closure. ' A close look at the democratization and crystallization of access to opportunities reveals that the differences may be due to the 'historical specificity' of the writers. Those writing during economic expansion talk of democratization, whereas those writing during hard times speak of crystal- lization. What we may have here is a situation reflecting the education and occupational market at specific points in time. Thus, the indications are that the nature of the opportunity structure in a society at the time when one enters the labor force is of major consequence for mobility. Democratization and crystallization may not necessarily be contradictory as such but may reflect the influence of the changing socioeconomic struc- ture on individual mobility. This is the major underlying hypothesis we seek to test. 34 We now differentiate these questions into a number of specific hypotheses which will be tested using cohort analysis. Hypotheses i. "The greater the supply of educated laborers in a social- economic system the higher will be the level of education required for specific occupations in which educational requirements are variable." This hypothesis reflects what Bowles (1978) has called 'credential inflation' caused by educational expansion designed to appease or buy off real or imaginary opposition groups. In Zambia most of the population was excluded from education (especially secondary school and higher) during the colonial era. The struggle for independence was linked to popular demands for access to social opportunities -- especially jobs and schools. Education thus was made into a top priority, eventually consuming over 25% of the national budget. In this context then we would expect the younger workers to have on average more educational qualifications in any given occupation than will older workers. This is because the younger workers entered employment at a time when education became relatively wide- spread and hence presumably has an inflationary character on the require- ments for particular occupations. Concerning this hypothesis it is important to distinguish between 'level of education required for specific occupations' and 'level of education required by specific occupations.‘ In the former the relation- ship between educational levels and specific occupations is not a function of changes in the composition of occupation (i.e. nature of the task). This is the main meaning of credential inflation as used here. In the 35 latter, changes in the nature of the task i.e. occupations necessitate changes in the levels of education required to perform it adequately. Here we can talk of real changes in the requirement of education by specific occupations, whereas in the former the changes are purely inflationary. We see four (4) relationships between educational production and occupa- tional demand: a.) occupational demand is high while educational produc- tion is also high. There is potentially synchronized change and there- fore credential value inflation is minimal, and'if increases in education are proportional to increases in occupational demand, nonexistent. b.) occupational demand is high while educational production is low. There is no possibility of credential inflation and any change in the education required for specific occupations are real reflecting changes in the nature of the task. c.) occupational demand is low but educational production is high. In this situation credential inflation is highest and increases in the education required for specific occupations occur without no changes in the nature of those occupations. For example, if at one time one needed a primary school certificate to teach in primary school, at a later date one has to have a secondary school certificate even though the task of primary school teaching is essentially the same. d.) both educational production and occupational demand are low. We shall argue that these - four scenarios correspond to the Zambian social historical situation. Low educational production and low occupational demand was characteristic of very early colonial period (1896-1910). The advent of mining starting around the 19105 was one in which occupational demands based on mining rose but also one in which educational production was low. Large scale mining taking off in the late 19305, after the depression, and the growth 36 of African political and trade union movements saw a rise in both occupational demands and educational production. From the late 19605 to the present is a period in which there has occurred the so-called School Leaver problem,i.e. high unemployment levels among the young women and men leaving secondary school, and hence can be said to be a period of low occupational demands with relatively high education pro- duction. . ii. A second hypothesis is "As the amount of education in society, and the amount of education required for particular occupations increases, the amount of intergenerational occupational advantage transfer and the amount of intragenerational (within career) transfer of advantage also increases." Transfer of advantage is our focus. Differences in endowment of social economic attributes at fatherk level may lead to even more differences at sonb level. We perceive advantage as due to such things as incomes, locus i.e., rural or urban residence, cultural advantages in the home, occupational skills and other related attributes. If expansion of education implies more resource outlay to gain access to formal/industrial employment,then we would expect parents with initial advantages, i.e., wealthier, more educated and/or with high occupational status, to use their greater resources to help their offspring/dependents to gain better education and employment. In this case we would expect that current occupation would depend more on first job and respondents education (i.e. intragenerational transfer) in the younger population than in the older one. Similarly we would expect more intergenerational transfers (i.e. more influence of education and occupation of the father on the respondent's achievements/ status) in the younger cohort than in the middle and older cohorts. 37 This is because when formal education is spreading widely those entering the labor market have opportunities for mobility likewise affected. iii. Those who enter the labor market during periods of economic and occupational system transition experience much more intergenerational occupational mobility. In this respect we expect older population to experience more intergenerational occupational mobility. This is because older population enter the labor market at a time of more or less rapid transition from agrarian based to industrial based occupations. In con- trast younger cohorts enter the labor market when the industrial activity/ formal employment based occupational system has been consolidated. Data and Methodology The data analyzed here are from a project entitled "Urbanization, Housing and Employment in Zambian High Density Housing Area" conducted in 1973 by Professor David Wiley. In all 3,200 households were surveyed. Within these 3,200 households a random adult sample of 1,663 respondents was drawn of whom 884 were males and 779 were females. In this analysis only the random sample of males has been utilized. Path analysis models were utilized to test structural equations as specified in the Statistical Package for Social Sciences manual. We have regressed respondent's edu- cation on father's education and father's occupation, and respondent's first job on his education and father's occupation and finally respondent's current job on his first job, education, and father's occupation. We also used zero-order correlations and cross tabulations. As already noted, we are mainly dealing with cohort effects, i.e. the fact that birth cohorts experience different social economic conditions made us examine occupational and educational attainments of each of the three cohorts separately 38 so that we could compare them, thereby hoping to gauge the separate effects that the changing character of institutions and historical pro- cesses entail for occupational mobility. The prestige scale utilized in path analysis was derived, as shown in Appendix 1, from the Inter- national Standard Occupational Prestige Scale (Treiman 1977) and the Zambian Scale (Lay 1975). A large proportion of the 779 females con- sisted of those not employed outside the home and therefore could not be included in the path model regression equations. Thus, we have focused only on the 884 males. CHAPTER IV Results and Analysis and Discussion Characteristics of our 3 City Male Random Sample How representative of the population is the three city male random sample used in our analysis? There is no sure way of answering this ques- tion in the present circumstances. The characteristics of the Zambian population noted here are derived from the 1969 Population Census (Zambia, 1970). The three city sample survey was carried out in 1973, there- fore a comparison of the two has the drawback of not taking into account changes due to migration, politics, administration, etc. between 1969 and 1973. Secondly, our random sample was carried out in urban areas, where- as the 1969 population census is not broken down in rural or urban categories. Therefore, a comparison of population characteristics of 1969 census to our 1973, three city sample is strictly an estimation. On one hand, we find a low correspondence between the distribution of education in the population as a whole in the country and the educa- tional distribution in our three city, male random sample: 39 40 TABLE 4 Comparative Distribution of Education of all Employed Males Not Attending School Zambia, 1969, Compared with Male Education in the Three City Sample, 1973 Education M Middle Ed. (in years) 1969 1973 1969 1973 1969 1973 Census* Sample No Schooling (O) 28.6% 9.0% 25.7% 16.2% 61.6% 32.6% Lower Prim. (1-4) 25.8 9.0 31.5 24.0 24.4 29.3 Upper Prim. (5-8) 31.4 41.6 25.2 44.8 10.5 32.2 Secondary (9-13) 12.1 36.9 3.1 14.8 1.1 2.8 Post Sec. (14 and above) 0.1 1.5 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.0 Not Stated 1.7 1.8 0.8 0.0 0.4 0.0 % Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% N (total) 299,969 322 225,614 283 ‘ 36,427 279 *Census data is from Central Statistical Office Yearbook, 1970 Table 310. The distribution of education between urban and rural areas of Zambia does differ, therefore an urban sample will not necessarily represent the distribution of education in the country as a whole, hence, the low correspondence characterizing the above Table 4. 0n the other hand, as we break our working population into occupational categories we find a high correspondence between the census population and our random sample proportions as shown in the table below: 41 TABLE 5 Distribution of Employment Among Zambian Males in 1969 Census and in 1973, Three City Random Sample Occupational Category 1969 1973 Census* Three City Random Sample Professional/technical 2.9% (1.6%)**‘ 4.8% Administrative/managerial 1.8 (1.0) 1.1 Clerical 14.8 (8.1) 10.1 Sales 9.4 (5.1) 8.1 Service 21.7 (11.1) 11.5 Production/transport 49.3 (11.8) 48.1 Agricultural/forestry -- (27.0) 2.3 Total N 729,800 884 * Census figures from C.S.0. Yearbook, 1969, Table 419. ** Bracketed figure is calculated as percentage of whole labor force (i.e. not limited to urban working population). Except for agriculture most of the other occupations are concentrated in urban areas. When we exclude agriculture we find some proportional correspondence between the 1969 census and our 1973, three city random sample. This correspondence is weak or disappears when we include agri- cultural sector occupations in our calculation of percentage proportions as shown in bracketed figures in above Table 5. This is especially so for production and agricultural occupations, because these are the ones most affected by rural and urban differences. Thus almost all agricultural 42 occupations are in rural areas. In summary, we can say that our three city male random sample seems to be quite representative of urban males and not of the whole country. In other words, we have an urban bias. Comparing Fathers to Sons Because of the urban bias we cannot compare percentages of sons in agriculture with that of fathers in this sample. The two are incomparable because whereas all our male respondents were or are urban, not all fathers are. We can make comparisons with regard to the other occupations because they are urban based, and hence there is a high probability that in this case the fathers of our respondents were also in urban areas. Looking at Tables 6 and 7 we find that for professional/technical and related occupations all the sons had some formal education, while 22.2% of the fathers did not. But even this 22.2% of the fathers consisted of traditional healers and preachers who were classified as professionals. The majority of the fathers in professional/technical occupations (i.e. 44.4% in Table 7) had an upper primary education. The majority of the sons (i.e. 60.4% in Table 6) in professional/technical occupations had a secondary school education. The average educational achievement of sons in professional/technical occupations is secondary school (i.e. above 9 years) in contrast to that of the fathers is upper primary school (i.e. above 4 years of school). Thus there has been an increase in the mean level of education from father to son. This increase in the mean level of education from father to son is characteristic of all the other occupational categories. Substantial increases occur in administrative/managerial occupations (i.e. from primary 43 k.e a.” k.e m.e e.m e.m ~.FP a.a eateeaeeu to area» east 4, so. LN owe No_ Ne om op me 2 Peace to a m.. m.P_ e.~ P.me m..p ..m ..o_ _.. m.e seesaw .eeee to u ne.ea moo, ue.ma um.am uk.am um.ao um.om goo, woo_ ue.mm peace 3 .dlq. .31 4.191 3 m4: 3| 3 3: e... 23. 2; : m.mp m._~ ~.- m.a _.a Q.“ e.ap a.me c.0w e.oe m. - a L.am o.o N.m~ m.m~ e.ee ~.mm e.ee a.mm o.op a.e~ m - m m.o~ m.m~ o.mp m.m~ ..e~ e.e~ N.- a.m o.o m.e e - _ ne.a. mo.om um.m~ um.mm ua.a_ um.om um.m_ n~.~ ao.o no.0 . o gmsuc . Esme: .3... 2.5L... mu timm mm pom :0 :0 8 . cm! :08. \em< \eeea \e.se< \eoea Ameee>v Peace myoumuou Facoruoazouo unueo>mvgu< pacoeuausum Mm omen» on» cw s “GPO meeeeeoamee use: .e_e2em sate ommuou panopuaaauuo an aco5m>owgu< copumuzum m m4m cam: m.o— e.¢m m.m— o.e p.m m._ m.o p.m orgasm Co punch x mm ch map pe KN up w me 2 pouch no.oo— uo.oo— um.mm nm.mm uo.co_ um.ma um.mm ac.oop um.ma a peach Q2 98 NM: 1:1 2 an 3. fl... 141.41 8:382: p.o o.c o.o o.o o.o o.o o.o o.o ~.~ o>ono ecu cp m.m p.~ m.o m.~ ¢.~ F.PF c.- m.mm m.np m— u m o.¢— m.e m.m m.- —.n— m.m~ «.pm o.m~ ¢.¢¢ m n m ..~. —.~ ~.m p.m~ _.~p ¢.~ m.ep o.m~ a.m c u _ u~.mm ua.op um.m~ uh._¢ u_.mm um.—m um.~e uo.o u~.- o peach Locuo acumoLou utoamcot» oup>uom mopom peeved—u pupgomucuz puovcsump Amtoo>v noxopasmca mg:»—:u.gm< coruoam0ta o>FueLumC=vEu< (becovmmuwoga co.uauauu agomoueu —o:o.uaa=uuo mnmp .xgommuau paco_uua=uuo xa upgeum suvu «much :' mucovcoamuz ope: use we memguau to unpacreuu< panopumusum s w4mu.=ue .ocovuuuacm mo ommto>a paco_uo= use « emu N.“ ~.e o.o m.o m.~ m.o— . ~.__ N... m.c acne» mew m.¢ . m.m m.e p.¢ o.m m.~ m.m m.m m.o opach m- ~.p p.m m.m o.m m.m M.“ -- p.m o.¢ upo coxdpaeo xgumogou utogmcut» ouv>tom mopom pauvto_u pevtmmocuz pouvcguoh «cam: «Fugum -c: otzupauvtm< covuuaootal, ospaetumwcwse< pacovmmmeota Facovumz usagou pouch :oFuuuzum mo menu» new: o—QEum xJFU cough :_ agomoumu —m:opaoa:ouo x: mugozou ope: an umcwnuu< covuauscm to msem> com: m m4mmzo: .Acnucza can :o—m :P >Fm>wuuoammt Numutvcm oae. ..o._v nofi acmetao new harem mpmznw>pu=w mo mucme=quao immune we» cw escapees? amoe-ompm m? cowumuaum mucmucoammm opm. ..m.vv appmcopumemcmmgmuc? ommucu>um to sommcugu me» :P apnoPsm> acaaioaew once mg» mp covunuaum m.tmgumu .covueosuo mcp>po>cv use as» one umgmrpnmpmm mcgmuama pumsmu umomcogpm we» noon ca .Acmucza use ampm cw Anompv :mozao ecu smpm we page o» Fence pmsozom mpgu to comvsmaeou woven a axes on mcvumogmpcv m? be «a .mauaum umuvsmgcp so» covenaco ago a? vmcpapaxm we: mucmreo> mo pesoEm we» ..o.w .mgmacm m voumancm acommgamg mumxumin :p guess: use a Haem.H new emetu .mae a Npm. .ozuu mudgumm llmmll owe. now acogsau .mom - - mom. . m. - - .uzom .mwm Hmkm.u .1. ..moeuz .mea. .a_a5em eoeeee have merge we» es meeeeee ea< F_. Let mucovcoamoa crepe: ecu macmvcoamwa «pm: on mgmgpuu sot» mucmpwgmgcm maumom pucorumaauuo ecu chomumuaum Co «acupuvmemoo cowmmmimmm um~vvtmu=mum new: mpmuoz some 0 mmawmm .968 22:... I; I. . . ~ .\ 52 .xpm>wuumammt masccou tomcaoz new «peeve cu .tmupo eon» meow acmsgzu one umtve muzwucoammi .covumoacm mucmncoammt mcp>Po>cp mccvuoaam mzovcu> mg» cw umcwmpaxm no: mucovge> to pesoEm on“ .Amgmzam g uoamznum ..u.vv mpmacvmug use maoxumsn cw necesse ugh .mugogou gmmcsox can .mpuvve .sovpo any to zpm>vpumamms mucmeuwtmmou eowmmmtmms umNPuLmucmum seem mommgacoima c? necessc ugh « news. .opm. .wkm.u Boa emcee .mmm ”apes. .omo. .mpo.v .azouo memgumu . .-o.uw1.- - ./ now acmtgau .mmm ”mes. .Peo / — Lace. .LeN. .mmm.v . Hake. .eom. .opa.u ~ -L _. r .83 Bel—A 32. .SN. .3: we...” mafia“. Rx ”Pee. .oek. .mmm.H “no“ u zv a usogou mm< on mcwugouu< oPanm save oats» cw smegma meow segue: new com on mtonumu sot» mucmuvtmgcm mzuoum paccpymazuuo ecu pacowuauauu eo mucmvuwemmoo cowmmogmmz cmNPctmucmum newnvpvua pone: some a maze”; 53 composition of jobs rise) 50 will intragenerational and intergenerational transfer of occupational privileges. In other words, we eXpect that the direct effects of status attainment variables on the social economic po- sitions of our respondents in the path model will be higher for the younger cohort than for the middle and for the older cohorts. According to our second hypothesis the older cohort should con- versely experience much more intergenerational occupational mobility. In other words, we expect the least influence on the status attainment of the older cohort from father's education and occupation. We are using the path models to test this hypothesis. We begin by considering intergenerational status transfers, that is, the effects of father's education on respondent's education and the effects of father's occupation on respondent's education, first and current jobs. Then we will consider the effects of intragenerational status on respondent's occupa- tional status. We will analyze the effects of respondent's education on re- spondent's first and current jobs and the effect of respondent's first job on current job. A. Intergenerational Status Transfers The first pattern of causation we identify here is that of the ef- fect of father's occupation on respondent's current job. The variation in respondent's current occupation due to the influence of father's occupation is indeed very small and in the case of the older cohort, negligible; how- ever, the variation in current job due to influence from father's occupation was unexpected in that it was less in the younger cohort than in the middle cohort contrary to the prediction in Hypothesis 2. How do we account for- this unexpected finding, i.e. the variation due to father's occupation for 54 the younger cohort's current job (4.3%) being smaller than that for the middle cohort (6.1%). It is attractive to believe that this is due to the nature of the sample of current occupation for the younger cohort. The occupational cases declared missing, i.e. belonging to unclassified cate- gories such as unemployed, student, etc. was high in the younger cohort (Table 9). TABLE 9 Percentage of Cases Missing from Path Model Percentage of Cases Missiggfrom Path Model Cohort CUrrent *First Father's Res. Father's Av Category Job Job Ed. Ed. Job Tota1 01d 11.0% 3.9% 10.0% 1.4% 8.5% 5.9% Middle 8.4 2.8 0.0 5.5 7.4 4.8 Young 21.0 18.0 10.0 1,§_ 11.0 12.3 Total Sample 90 » 54 45 21 52 55 The younger cohort (Table 9) has a comparatively high share of missing cases from regression models overall and especially with regard to current job. This could be said to be a distorting effect on the variation in younger cohort's current job, explained by father's occupation; but the trouble with this explanation is that missing data in current job does not have a similar effect on the path from first job. More importantly we believe this might be due to rapid social change (as represented by political independence) leading to decreased effects. The second causal pattern we have established is that of the varia- tion in respondent's education due to the influence of father's occupation, 55 as shown in Figure 0 is 18.9%, 8.8%, and 27.4% for the older, middle, and younger cohorts respectively. It was expected according to predictions in hypothesis 2, that the causal influence of father's occupation on respond- ent's education should be highest in the younger cohort. It was not ex- pected, and hence contrary to predictions in the second hypothesis that the least causal influence on respondent's education by father's occupa- tion will be in middle cohort and not in the older cohort. The reason for this apparently is connected to the historical background of the country, especially the development of the labor force and the occupational system. At the time the older cohort was in school or entering the labor market, education and its associated colonial bureaucracies were derived mainly from missionary activity and, in the main, considered alien. It was those with occupations associated to missionary activity and public bureaucracies who sent their dependents to school. This was so because early British colonial policy aimed at having a set of functionaries to help carry out low, semi- 1iterate jobs in the bureaucracy. In time, these lower functionaries even came to link education to monetary rewards. In contrast, the middle cohort was in school, i.e. from the late 19405, when there was more urban growth and large scale mining methods towards the close of the 19305. It was dur- ing this time that political demands for more benefits to the indigenous people began. The colonial development plans and the increase in primary education (discussed in Chapter II) should be seen in this context. Colonial authorities instituted some compulsion for lower levels of education. For instance, an individual was liable for punishment if he kept a primary school age child out of school in the early years of the Federation. Thus, the number of children at primary school was raised to over 50% of those in the age bracket, a large raise in the colonial situation; therefore, for 56 the middle cohort the variation in respondent's education will depend less on the father's occupation because education is widespread, throughout all occupations. On the other hand, the younger cohort attended school when it was clearly linked to social rewards through the daily altercations of po- litical debate on justice and equality (especially in the 1962 elections). Education was linked to social rewards (i.e. mainly in the form of prestige and high salaries) when the older and middle cohort were at school. But the possibilities of realizing this link was limited because of the racial segregation of occupations and colonial policies which discouraged Africans from aspiring to higher education by denying them facilities and high pay- ing jobs. For the younger cohorts, father's occupation becomes important in realizing high educational levels, because after independence there is higher competition for school positions. This competition increases with levels of education such that those with greater resource possessions (high- er occupation) are better able to have their children in school and not working at home. It does not follow that if the father is more educated the son also is more educated. Our third pattern of intergenerational occupational transfer shows that the variation in respondent's education due to the influence of father's education is 19.4% 28.9%, and 12.8% for the respec- tive older, middle and younger cohorts. Clearly enough then, the respond- ent's education is for the younger cohorts less dependent on father's edu- cation. We believe this reflects the massive increase in educational levels after independence. Thus, as we saw earlier post-colonial increases in primary education was such that by 1970, almost 90% of those eligible to attend primary classes were at school, a considerable increase from the 1963 figure of approximately 50%. Expansion of primary and secondary 57 schools in Zambia has been the most rapid in post-colonial Africa (Elliot, J. 1975). At the same time unemployment had been increasing, such that it did not necessarily follow that once a person had high education he could have a high prestige job. In this situation in which the young cohort finds itself the effect of father's education, unless they have a high job, will not greatly affect variation in the respondent's education. The fourth and last pattern of intergenerational transfer is the effect of father's occupation on respondent's first job. As expected according to prediction from hypothesis 2 this variation was greater for the younger cohort than for the middle and older cohorts (i.e. 6.1%, 5.0%. 1.3%). In this case we can say that father's occupation is increasingly a mechanism for the transfer of perlleQG t0 f1'5t 30b: TABLE 10 Summary of Results Pertaining to Intergenerational Transfer of Privilege Causal patterns of intergenera- tional transfer Hypothesis 2 (Prediction: more *(Prediction: less privilege transfer privilege transfer in young cohort) in old cohort) Variation in dependent vari- able due to inde- pendent variable Confirmed Confirmed Effect of fa- Older cohort = ther's occu- 0.2% pation on sons Middle cohort =- No Yes current job 6.1 Younger cohort = 4.3 Effect of fa- Older cohort = ther's occupa- 18.9% tion on son's Middle cohort = . education 8.8 Yes No Younger cohort = 27.4 TABLE 10 (Cont'd) Effect of father's 58 Older cohort = education on son's 19.4% education Middle cohort = No No 28.9 Younger cohort = 12.8 Effect of father's Older cohort = occupation on son's 1.3% first job Middle cohort = Yes Yes 5.0 Younger cohort = 6.1 As the above Table 10 summary of results of the effect of father's social economic position on son's career indicates, we have obtained mixed results. The prediction in Hypothesis 2, namely that father's social economic position will have greater effect on the career of the younger cohort has been confirmed in two paths and not in two others. We have explained this nonconfirmation in the two other paths as possibly due to historical conditions which uniquely applied to the young cohort as they were in school and/or entering the labor force and by the nature of the sample. Again Hypothesis 2 we predicted that father's socioeconomic position will have the least causal effect on the achievements of the older cohort because they entered the labor force at the time of rapid transition from agrarian to industrial occupations. firmed in two paths and not in two others. Again, this prediction has been con- In other words, our data offers limited support to the hypothesis that as amount of formal educa- tion spreads in a given society so will the effect of father's occupation and education on son's achievements. The nature of the data we are using 59 does not allow us to clearly distinguish between the confounding effects of career stage from historical period in which cohort entered labor force. 8. Intragenerational (within career) Status Achievements The first causal pattern we identify here is that of the variation in respondent's current job (1973) due to the influence of the respondent's education. The variation in the respondent's current job due to the influence of respondent's education is 22.0%, 43.7% and 24.0% for the respective older, middle and younger cohorts. According to our predic- tions in Hypothesis 2, we are supposed to have greater variance explained in the younger than in the middle cohort. We expect the younger cohort to increase the level of association also as an artifact of method in which the time distance between education and current job is for them shortest; however, this was not so. This unexpected result is due to the fact that the younger cohort is experiencing a situation of increased education which is having an inflationary effect on occupations (as seen in creden- tial inflation hypothesis). Moreover, their social situation is one of political dislocation, i.e. changes from colonial to post-colonial society which serve as channels of mobility to positions of authority or to po- sitions reflecting contribution to political struggle regardless of edu- cation. In other words, for the younger cohort entering the labor market after 1964, the year of self-government, education is not enough to at- tain high prestige occupations other, mainly political, considerations came in. The second causal pattern we were able to establish here is that of the effect of respondent's first job on respondent's current job. The 60 variation in respondent's current job due to influence of the respondent's first job is 10.6%, 12.0%, and 29.8% for the respective older, middle and younger cohort groups. The result confirmed our prediction in Hypothesis 2 that the younger c0hort will have the most variation in current job due to first job. In other words, the quality of first job increasingly affects one's advancement in his occupational career. People with high prestige first occupations may increasingly more likely advance in their occupational careers. The third causal pattern we have derived is that of the effect of respondent's education on respondent's first job. The variation in first job due to influence of the respondent's education is 19.8%, 43.2%, and 50.7% for the older, middle, and younger cohort groups. Here the result confirmed our prediction in Hypothesis 2, that the younger generation will experience much more mobility within career depending on their education. In summary, concerning intragenerational occupatibnal mobility of our respondents the results show two paths confirming that it is increas- ingly dependent on quality of first job and, more importantly, on one's education. One path did not confirm this. On the whole, we can assert that advancement within careers depends on the quality of first job and more on education obtained by people. With regard to Figure 0 we have noted the problem of how to separate career stage from historical period in which a cohort entered the labor force remains unresolved because of the nature of our data. However, the separate career stage of the three cohorts may provide an alternative explanation for the high standardized regression coefficients of the middle cohort in three paths. Blau and Duncan (1967, p. 187) established that 'factors salient at an early stage of man's career may continue to play a direct role as he grows 61 older.‘ But the direct effects of education and father's status are attenu- ated directly with the passage of time. A compensatory effect is the in- creasing relevance of the accumulation of occupational experiences as time passes. The implication relevant to Figure 9 is that the younger cohort has lower regression coefficients than middle cohort in some paths as shown in summary Table 7 because they had had less time to advance beyond father's occupation, or perhaps, to have influence of father's occupation take effect. The older cohort may be at a stage where father's background may not be ex- ercising that much influence, i.e. they depend more on their own career, whereas for the middle cohort, father's careers influence may be at its peak. In Figure 0 the residuals, i.e. variance unexplained in the equation are rather high. For the older cohort unexplained variance range from .895 to .978; from .749 to .904 for the middle cohort; and from .641 to .877 for the younger cohort. The interesting point to note is that though the re- siduals are high, they become smaller as we move from the older to the mid- dle and younger cohorts. The basic point is that with the consolidation of the social structure i.e. patterns of association, stratification, work, etc. originating with the imposition of colonialism; mobility becomes more predictable according to the set of variables included in this model. Re- searchers in Zambia have found that the variance not explained in regression equations is generally high (Wiley 1971, 1979). In Hypothesis 3 we predicted that the older cohort should experience more mobility than the other cohorts because they are entering the labor market during a period of economic and occupational transition i.e. from subsistence agriculture to one of dependent industrial development, and the occupational systems they engender. We test this hypothesis using a mobility table i.e. Table 11. In this table respondents are concentrated in four occupational categories i.e. professional/technical; service, production/ 61a nu ma. Nu m m N ucso N4 N2 2 N N N m" 28:». z 2:: on Na. N. p e -- N_ ape _.Nm an o.N. a. m.m. op MN.SN N c.cN _ .o.cc_. N N.N. a mega» meaeh\.eoea NHeN NN Nnom No WN.NNM __ N.ee N N.ae N .e.o. o o..N __ o.ee.: N an N. N Na so e.om a .e.e a e.mN . -- o.Nm e_ e_o _.. N m.e N e.e e e.e e e.e c Mo.ew o o.o e oesoN .msz .e<\te< o.e o N.. N o.e e e.c e o.e e e.e o o.o e o_ee.x a.N N N.N N. N.N . o.o o o.e o -- .m.e. N e_o o.N N N.N. m. AN.NN m Ae.e o o.o a Mo.e o o.o e mesa» moustam N.. N N.N. NN In.m . IN.NN . o.e o o.e e e.o e o.ee.: .N... m ..cN NN .e.mN N Ae.e a e.o e -- N.m . e_o e.a N .N.N. m. m.. _ .AN.N . Ao.o _ Me.e e N.. N mesa» mo_em N.. N Mo.e .. e.e o .o.c o .o.e e o.c e o.o c o.ee.: N.m N N.» a .N.o. N .o.oe_ . .c.em N -- Aa.mp N ope A..a_ N. m.NN N. N.N_ . e.o o .e.e _ AN.. . mesa» _ao.eo.u .m.o . e.N_. oN N.m_ N c.o o Ae.e e Ao.ee_. . ..m_ N o.oe.: .N... e ..o. e. e.o. e o.e o .e.mN _ -- m.o. N 5.: t- -. .. -- -- .. 9:36» .cm:\.:.sv< AN.N. . .o.o. o e.o. e Ao.e. o Ae.oe o Ao.c. e o o.ee.: -- -- -- -- -- -- -- v.8 N.N a m.N N A—.N N . o.o e o.oe N e.e e AN..N _ oeeo» ooe\oea ..N . N.N N. A...N . o.e e N.NN _ .o.e e .o.e e o.eoex ANN.N _ ANN._ n Ae.e a e.o o o.e. e AN- - ANN.m . 8.: .aeaLNNaoea .aex .e<\eo< oo.seom ao_.m .ao.eo_u .eaz\.e< ooPNoea Neooooeo eo_o_moa Nemmota Ange—uNmoa u—locouo N-Noom m.gogu~m .0... mucoucoamoc No mcvavgc popuom auogou muemveoamuu .NeN.z. «€28 2: a £23. :5 3...: 5 35288.. 2.: of to 52.5 .38... : oz: 62 transport/equipment operation and agricultural/animal husbandry and forestry occupations. The whole mobility table shows that there is high mobility between occupations. Most of the children of fathers with professional/ technical occupations end up in production and transport occupations (i.e. 52.6%, 84.6%, and 42.9% for the older, middle and younger cohorts respect- ively). Similarly most respondents with service occupation fathers end up with production transport occupations (i.e. 50%, 58%, and 45% for the older, middle and younger cohorts respectively). Still, again most respon- dents with fathers in agricultural occupations end up in production and transport occupations (57%, 56%, and 43%). In all these mobility patterns there is no substantial differences between the three cohorts. This may be because though the older cohort experienced the transition from agriculture and subsistence based occupations to those which are greatly influenced by industrial activity the other cohort i.e. the middle and younger one have been in a period of rapid social change which also makes it possible for them to move to other occupational categories. However, there is an interesting pattern with regard to self- recruitment within production/transport/equipment operation occupations. There is high self-recruitment within production/transport] and equipment operation occupations. The highest self-recruitment is with the middle cohort, (55.9%, 76.2% and,52.1% for the older, middle, and younger cohorts respectively). This again may be related to the confounding effects of career stage and historical period which cannot be segregated out in our data. The youngest cohort showing lower self-recruitment may be due to the possibility that they are not yet at level of occupations which social background will eventually "produce." On the other hand, oldest cohort may be more influenced by prior occupational experience than by background. 63 Self-recruitment in other occupational categories is low across cohorts. Mobilit Within and Between Generation BEEEEV6%_Zero Order Correlations Below in Table 12, we see the zero order correlations of the various variables in the path diagrams of Figures C and 0. Table 8 reflects effects corresponding to the standardized regression coefficients discussed in Figure C except for some of the cases dealing with respondent's current occupation. Concerning intergenerational transfers, we have similar patterns of association in the following: the relationship between father's educa- tion and respondent's education (i.e. .261, .308, and .273 correlations for the respeCtive older, middle and younger cohorts); the relationship between father's occupation and respondent's education (i.e., .213, .152, and .301 correlation for older, middle and younger cohorts); and the relation- ship between father's occupation and respondent's first job (i.e. .013, .050, and .061 correlation for the respective older, middle and younger cohorts). One pattern of association of intergenerational transfer did not correspond to the pattern established in path model. The relationship between father's occupation and-respondent's current occupation showed the younger cohort having the highest association between the two variables (i.e. .003, .165, and .234 correlation). For within generation status achievement, we also obtained similar patterns of association between variables except one involving current occupation. Thus, the association between respondent's education and respondent's first job shows a pattern corresponding to that in path model (i.e. .193, .473, and .527 correlation for the respective cohorts). 64 co.— > oo.p z Amhmpv now anagram oo.p o m.ucou=oamwm mpm. oo.p > Nmm. oo.p s new umspu NNN. oo.p o m.Neooeoemoe new. sum. oo.p > pmc. nee. oo.p : cowaouzum New. may. oo.p o m.u=mo=oammm emu. . mew. pom. oo.p > mop. pup. Nmp. oo.p z cowumazouo moo. one. mpN. oo.F o m.gmspou eNN. amp. NNN. Noe. oo._ MNW tomeaoN omN. pom. mom. New. oo.p z mpuuN: :owuouaum may. amp. _oN. NNN. oo.N Ace roepo m.eaeoeu Amumpv neonate; ..=ovuou:uuM copuoaauuc cowamoaum utosoo mmpnmwsm> aoa pcmgeau m.p=muconmwm m.u:mu=oqmmm m.sm;uou m.sw;uma maumam m.u=mu=oamom mNmp Agmmeso> new opener .gouFoV mugogou mm< :mNBEmN water we» not newscwmau +.o¢v upc newcws opaom omen, new mcmpa acmsaopo>oc .mpcopoo guy: auto» caonap mo P.m mmm ac.~m gowmcoaxm twang muvzc comp . ommp Annam> mmiomv apnea: sopnosa gozop Foogom \ucmszapasmca mcvmomco ism .aocu maps; can ecu Leave «so .mcmpq ~.m NNm u¢.mm acasaapa>au Pa.=o_au Pea. emote Amaaa> m~-mpv amen guv: twang >gm> maze» oucom.gona4 umuopgsou pcogom u z orgasm pouch cw spasm mo wave ogu mosom Lona; xgommamu ugozou mo menu> cam: mo acmugmm an ugogou bosom Lona; mam: ca xcucm usosou mgu.$o muvumpcmauacmgu co manna umumswumm Roam u zv mum. .aPasam sauce: save awash as» to maaogoo am< ago to no.8a.aaouatagu .a. apaah BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Adler, Chaim 1974 "Social Stratification and Education in Israel” Comparative Education Review 18:10-23. Alker, Howard 1976 "Boudons Educational Thesis About the Replications of Social Inequality” Social Science Information 15:33-46. Andorka, Rudolph 1976 "Social Mobility and Education in Hungary: An Analysis Applying Boudons Models" Social Science Information l5:47-70. Baco, M. 1971 "Intergenerational Occupational Mobility in the Phillipines“ Phillipine Sociological Review 19:193—208. Belan, J., H. Browning, E. Jelin 1973 Men in a Developing Society. Austin: University of Texas Press. Baldwin, Robert 1966 Economic Development and Export Growth. Los Angeles: University of California Press. Batzell, E. 1958 Philadelphia Gentleman. New York: Free Press. Berger, Elena 1974 Labor, Race and Colonial Rule. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Blau, Peter, Otis, Duncan l967 The American Occupational Structure. New York; Wiley and Sons. Boudon, Robert 1974 Education, Opportunity and Social Inequality. New York: Wiley. 1976 "Comments on Hausers Review of Education, Opportunity and ' Social Inequality" American Journal of Sociology 81:1175-77. Bowles, Samual 1978 "Capitalist Development and Educational Structure" World Development 6:783-796. Braverman, Harry 1974 Labor and Monopoly Capital. New York: Monthly Review Press. 83 84 Burawoy, Michael 1977 "Social Structure, Homogenization and the Process of Status Attainment in the U.S.A. and U.K." American Journal of Sociology 82:1031-42. Buckley, Walter 1958 "Social Stratification and the Functional Theory of Social Differentiation" American Sociological Review 23:369-75. Carlson, Gosta. Katarina, Karlson 1970 "Age, Cohorts and the Generation of Generations" American Sociological Review 35:710-18 Clignet, Remi 1966 The Fortunate Few. Evanston. Coombe, Trevor 1967 "Origins of Secondary Education in Zambia.“ African Social Research 1:173-205. Coser, Lewis 1975 "Presidential Address: Two Methods in Search of a Substance" American Sociological Review 40:691-700. Crowder, David. 1974 "A1Critique of Duncans Stratification Research" Sociology 8: 9-45. Currie, J. 1975 Secondary School Selection and Occupational Placement in Uganda Ph.D. University of Chicago. Davis, Kingsley, Wilbert Moore 1945 "Principles of Social Stratification" American Sociological Review 10:242-9. Domhoff, A. 1958 The Higher Circles New York:. Vintage Books Duncan, Otis 1966 "Methodological Issues in the Analysis of Social Mobility" in Moore, W.E. (ed) Indicators of Social Change. New York: Russel Sage Foundations. . Elliot, Charles 1971 Constraints on the Economic Development of Zambia. Nairobi: Oxford University Press. Elliot, J. 1975 "Education in Zambia" South African Journal of African Affairs 5:3-9. 85 Farooq 1973 Economic Growth and Changes in the Industrial Structure of Labor Force in Pakistan Economic Development and Cultural Change 21:293-308. Faunce, William, William Form 1969 Comparative Perspectives on Industrial Society. Boston: Little Brown Company. Featherman, D. 1974 "Review of the Analysis of Social Mobility: Methods and Approaches" Contemporary Sociology 3:33-36. Forster, Phillip 1980 "Education and Social Inequality in Sub Saharan Africa" Journal of Modern African Studies 18:201-236. Fry, James ‘ 1979 Employment and Income Distribution in the African Economy. London: Croom Lelm. Glass, David 1954 Social Mobility in Britain. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Gould, W. 1971 “Geography and Educational Opportunity in Tropical Africa" Tijdsl Lrift Voor Economische en Souale Geographie 62:82-9. Gouldner, Alvin 1970 The Coming Crisis of Western Sociology. New York: Basic Books. Hagenaars, J. Cobben, N. 1978 "Age, Cohort and Period: A General Model for the Analysis of Social Change" Netherlands, Journal of Sociology. Haller, Archibald, Alejandro Portes 1973 "Status Attainment Processes" Sociology of Education 46:51-91. Hauser, Robert 1976 "Review of Education, Opportunity and Social Inequality" American Journal of Sociology. 81:911-28. Heisler, Helmut 1971 "The African Work Force of Zambia" Civilization. 4:425-434. Hicks, R. 1966 "Occupational Prestige and its Factors" African Social Research. Horan, Patrick 1978 "Is Status Attainment Research Atheoretical?“ American Sociological Review 43:534-41. 1974 "The Structure of Occupational Mobility -- A Conceptualization and Analysis“. Social Forces 53:33-45. 86 Hvaco, G. . 1963 "A Logical Analysis of the Davis Moore Theory of Social Strati- fication" American Sociological Review 28:801-4. Jackman, Mary 1973 Recent Population Movements in Zambia. Lusaka: Institute for African Studies. Jahoda, Gustav 1954 “The Social Background of a West African Student Population" ' British Journal of Sociology 5:355-65. Kerr, Clark. John, Dunlop. Fredrick, Harbison. Charles Myers 1964 Industrialism and Industrial Man. New York: Oxford University Press. Kelly, J. Klein, H. Rubison, R. 1977 "Social Mobility in a Peasant Society" Chicago: American Sociological Association Annual Meeting. Kol oko, Edwin 1980 Manpower Approach to Planning. Graduate School of International Studies. University of Denver. Lay, Robert 1973 Zambian Occupational Ratings. Boston College. Unpublished. Lipset, Seymour R. Bendix 1959 Social Mobility in Industrial Society. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lisowski, Sdrzej 1978 "Mining as a Town Forming Factor in Countries of Tropical Africa“ Polish Sociological Bulletin 27:105-125. Lloyd, Peter 1974 Power and Independence: Urban Africans Perceptions of Social Inequality. London. Marx,Karl 1977 Capital Vol. 1 New York: Vintage Books 1981 The Germany Ideology. New York: International Publishers. Matras, Judan 1975 Social Inequality, Stratification and Mobility. New Jersey: Englewood Cliffs. Mbilinyi, Margaret . 1976 "Education, Stratification and Sexism in Tanzania" African Review 2:327-40. 8? Miller, S.M. 1970 "Comparative Social Mobility" Current Sociology 9:1-89. Mitchell, Clyde. A. Epstein 1959 "Occupational Prestige and Social Status Among Urban Africans in Northern Rhodesia" Africa 1:22-39. Moir, Hazel 1976 Relationships between Urban Level and Industrial Structure. Economic Development and Cultural Change 25:123-36. Mwanakafwe, John 1967 “The Progress of Education in Zambia" Optima 12:152-165. Mwanza, Jacob 1979 "Rural-Urban Migration and the Urban Employment in Zambia" Developing Economies 6:172-181. Noble, Trevor 1974 "Social Mobility and Theories of Social Stratification" Sociological Analysis and Theory 2:75-104. Olson, Jerry 1972 "Secondary Schools and Elites in Kenya" Comparative Educational Review 16:44-53. Parker, 3. Brown, R. Child, J. Smith, M. 1977 The Sociology of Industry. London: George Allen. Parson, Talcott 1954 Essays in Sociological Theory. New York: Free Press. Qvortrup, Jens 1979 “An Essay on Some Concepts in Stratification and Mobility" Acta Sociological 22:273-88. Raczynski, D. 1972 "A Note on Migration and Social Mobility in Chile" International Migration 6:183-99. Ramos, Joseph 1970 Labour and Development in L. America. New York: Columbia University Press. Robinson, R. 1978 "Ownership of Means of Production, Authority and Prestige" American Sociological Association Paper Presentation. Rogoff, Natalie 1975 "On Education, Opportunity and Social Inequality" Social Science Information 14:107-113. 88 Ryder, Norman 1965 “Cohort as a Concept in the Study of Social Change" American Sociological Review 30:843-61. Schneider, E. 1969 Industrial Sociology. New York: McGraw Hill. Sewell, W. Hauser, Robert 1975 Education, Occupation and Earnings. New York: Academic Press. 1976 Schooling and Achievement in American Society. New York: Academic Press. Simmance, A. ‘ 1976 "Urbanization in Zambia" Journal of Administration Overseas 10:498-504. Simmons, A. B. 1975 "Social Mobility in Bogota, Columbia" International Journal of Comparative Sociology 4:228-45. Soja, E. 1948 The Geography of Modernization in Kenya. Syracuse: University Press. Sorensen, A., "Models and Strategies and Research on Attainment and Opportunity" Social Science Information. Sorokin, Pitirim 1927 Social Mobility. New York: Harper and Brothers. Steen, S. - 1975 Economic Development and Demand for Manpower in Zambia. South African Journal of African Affairs 5:10-18. Sutcliffe, R. 1971 Industry and Underdevelopment. London: Addison Wesley. Svalastoga, K. 1959 Prestige, Class and Mobility. Copenhagen: Gylendal. Tawsky, Curt 1965 "Parsons on Stratification" Sociological Quarterly 6:128-138. Thompson , C. 1949 Economic Development in Rhodesia/Nyasaland. London: Dennis Dobson Limited. Treiman, D. J. 1977 Occupational Prestige in Comparative Perspective. New York: Academic Press. 89 Van den Berghe, Catherine, Nuttney 1969 "Some Social Characteristics of University Students" Nigerian Journal of Economic and Social Studies 3:355-77. Weis, Lois 1979 "Education and the Reproduction of Inequality" Comparative Education Review 23:41—51. Wesolowski, W. Slomczynski, K. Mach, 8. 1979 "Trends in Social Mobility Studies and Marxist Theory of Class Structure" Polish Sociological Bulletin 1:5-18. Wiley, David 1971 Social Stratification and Religion in Urban Zambia. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation. Princeton. . 1979 "Changing Patterns of Status Attainment in Urban Africa: A Cohort Analysis in the Zambian Labor Force" Unpublished paper. Zambia, Republic of . 1966 Manpower Report. Lusaka: Government Printer. 1970 "Census of Population and Housing, 1969, First Report." Central Statistics Office. Lusaka: Government Printer. "111 1111111711111111111