THE EFFECT OF RATE STRUCTURE UPON THE AVAILABILITY OF CREDIT AT CONSUMER FINANCE COMPANIES Thai: for fha flags-w oé Phi D. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY Maurice B. Goucizwaard ms IHESJS LIBRARY IIIIIIEII\\\I ”$1253?" 7--.-- - wok—wusfl -« This is to certify that the thesis entitled The Effect of Rate Structure Upon the Availability of Credit at Consumer Finance Companies presented by Maurice Goudzwaard ’ has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Business Administration flights/ii Major professor Date September 31 1965 0-169 h.___—.H__E # _ ABSTRACT THE EFFECT OF RATE STRUCTURE UPON THE AVAILABILITY OF CREDIT AT CONSUMER FINANCE COMPANIES by Maurice Goudzwaard The principal objective of this dissertation is to mea- sure the extent that higher rates persuade consumer finance companies to lend to riskier borrowers, or conversely, the extent that lower rates cause them to deny credit to marginal applicants. Since each state regulates the maximum allowable rate of charge, consumer finance companies impose varying finance rates depending on the legal regulations in the differ- ent states which they operate. This study concerns itself with the resulting effects of this variability on credit standards. Three methods were used to evaluate this relationship: 1) interviews to determine management policies and attitudes toward credit standard flexibility. 2) a regression analysis of state chargeoff rates, turndown rates, and finance rates of three major consumer finance companies. 3) a detailed comparison of the characteristics of persons receiving credit and those denied credit in Albany, New York, where lenders are permitted to charge only a relatively low rate, with loan applicants in Charleston, west Virginia where lenders charge a higher rate. u - Maurice Goudzwaard Each of these tests confirms the hypothesis of a positive refilationship between the finance rate charged by lenders and ‘the risk.accepted into their loan portfolios. The interviews indicated that major finance companies do not consciously adjust risk criteria because of rate differ— entials. Company executives indicate the profits earned in higher rate states compensate for the smaller earnings in lower rate states, resulting in credit standards being deter- mined on the basis of average cost and revenue analysis. However, most loan supervisors or "middle managers" who evaluate branch manager credit decisions tend to adjust loan quality criteria to earnings potentials implicit in rate levels and to adOpt more lenient credit standards in higher rate states. The mechanism of adjustment, however, is inexact. The first quantitative test uses data from three major finance companies and correlates state chargeoff rates, turn- down rates, gross yields, and average loan sizes to measure the relationship between risk acceptance and finance charge levels. A multiple correlation analysis using chargeoff rates as the dependent variable indicates a moderate rela— tionship between risk acceptance and gross yield, average loan size, and state per capita income. Simple and partial correlatitni analyses of chargeoff rates and gross yields Maurice Goudzwaard (lisplay a moderate correlation at each of the three firms. Turndown rates, used as a measure of risk acceptance, Iaave virtually no relationship with finance charges, both xdhen tested by simple and partial correlation. The third test analyzes data from branch offices of three major finance companies in Albany, New York and in Charleston, West Virginia. Characteristics of 200 borrowers and 200 rejected applicants from each office were compared to determine whether Charleston lenders accepted more risk because of their greater rate-earnings protection. As a means of measuring risk, two credit scoring systems were used--one based on consumer finance company data and the other on commercial bank experiences. The application of both scoring systems suggests there is virtually no difference between applicant personal characteristics in the two cities. An extended analysis of financial characteristics reveals applicants in Charleston have lower incomes and greater instalment debt and monthly payments, implying lenders in Charleston assume greater risks. This lower income and higher debt of applicants exists in spite of the higher income of the general pOpulation in Charleston as compared with Albany. It appears that borrowers in Charleston are eligible for approximately $400 more credit. The conclusiveness of the i ‘ I Maurice Goudzwaard evidence is somewhat mitigated by the larger prOportion of applicants living in owner occupied dwellings and the greater residence stability of applicants in Albany. On balance, lenders in Charleston accept greater risk and offer more credit to their borrowers. The management attitude survey and both quantitative tests confirm the hypothesis of a positive relationship be- tween finance charges and credit availability at consumer finance companies. This finding must be used in a guarded ‘way, however, since the reliability and validity of the con— clusions depend on the assumptions that l) chargeoff rates measure risk acceptance standards, and 2) the "independent" and smaller finance companies adOpt credit standards similar to those of the three major finance companies. Chargeoff rates presumably reflect credit quality, but in some instances collection and investigation expenses substitute for chargeoff expense, thereby rendering chargeoff rate a less valid mea- surement. Previous studies show the credit standards of smaller finance companies are similar to those of the larger firms, but further research is needed to confirm or refute this. The empirical evidence suggests higher rate ceilings permit borrowers to obtain more credit, although further Maurice Goudzwaard research is needed to accurately measure the extent of this variability. Whether or not more credit should be available tt) a larger segment of society is not a matter of economic science, but a social value judgment. THE EFFECT OF RATE STRUCTURE UPON THE AVAILABILITY OF CREDIT AT CONSUMER FINANCE COMPANIES BY A e) . rr Maurice B? Goudzwaard A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Accounting and Financial Administration 1965 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I thank the many peOple who encouraged and assisted me during my academic endeavors at Michigan State University. A jpartial listing includes only a few who have made my college education more rewarding and complete. The members of my dissertation committee were very con- structive and helpful with their refreshing and stimulating ideas. I am grateful to Professor James Stapleton for his .assistance, Professor James D. Edwards for his academic stimu- lation and financial assistance, and to Professor Roland I. Inabinson, my dissertation committee chairman, whose vitality arui sincere deducation I will always appreciate. I also thank Professor Robert W. Johnson for introducing nus to the world of Finance in general and the field of Consumer (:redit in particular. His academic and financial concern for xny education is most appreciated. The representatives of several consumer finance companies twere most helpful in allowing me to use and analyze their data. INithout them this dissertation would not be possible. I espe- cially thank Dr. Ernst A. Bauer and the management of Household Finance Corporation for providing the financial assistance needed to complete the dissertation research. My parents were very understanding and considerate of my educational pursuits and provided the family environment ii necessary to sustain my motivation and enthusiasm. My sincere appreciation to Judy whose thoughtful under- standing and patience made my educational efforts less arduous arui eminently worthwhile. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS................... ILIST OF CHARTS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . LIST OF TABLES 0 O O O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O O . ILIST OF APPENDICES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Chapter I II INTRODUCTION General Background . . . . . . . . . . . . Nature of the Study. . . . . . . . . . . . Purpose of the Project . . . . . . . . . . Significance of the Study. . . . . . . . . Importance and Role of Consumer Credit in our Economy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Consumer Finance Company Role in Credit Expansion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Approach to the Study. . . . . . . . . . . Organization of the Study. . . . . . . . . MANAGEMENT VIEW OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN RISK AND RATE Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Top Management View. . . . . . . . . . . . Middle and Lower Management View . . . . Effect of Management Evaluation Criteria on Loan Quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . Management Policies and Attitudes Toward Rate Levels. . . . . . . . . . . . Preferential Rates . . . . . . . . . C 0 0 Effect of Loan Size on Borrower Loan Eligi— bility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Management Attitude Toward Rate Regulation Influence of Other Variables . . . . Summary and Conclusions. . . . . . iv Page ii viii xiv \IO\~I>I-‘ ll 13 18 23 25 26 3O 32 35 4o 43 44 45 46 Chapter Page III EMPIRICAL RELATIONSHIP OF CREDIT STANDARDS AND RATE LEVELS TEST I Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 Data Used in Test I. . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 Measures of Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 Methods of Measuring Association . . . . . . 53 Expected Relationship Between Gross Yield and Chargeoff Rates. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 Expected Relationship Between Gross Yield and Turndown Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 Expected Relationship Between Per Capita In— come and Chargeoff Rates . . . . . . . . . 55 Expected Relationship Between Per Capita In- come and Turndown Rates. . . . . . . . . . 56 Expected Relationship Between Average Loan Size and Risk Acceptance . . . . . . . . . 56 Expected Relationship of Variables Indirectly Associated with Hypothesis . . . . . . . . 57 Empirical Evidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 Multiple Correlations. . . . . . . . . . 60 Relationship Between Chargeoff Rates and Gross Yields . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 Relationship Between Turndown Rates and Gross Yield. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 Relationship Between Chargeoff Rates and Average Loan Sizes . . . . . . . . . . 71 Relationship Between Turndown Rates and Average Loan Sizes . . . . . . . . . . 72 Relationship Between Chargeoff Rates and Per Capita Income. . . . . . . . . . . 73 Relationship Between Turndown Rates and Per Capita Income. . . . . . . . . . . 74 Summary of Relationship Between Risk and Independent Variables. . . . . . . . . . . 76 Regression Coefficients Indirectly Related to Hypothesis. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 Relationship of Per Capita Income and Gross Yield. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78 Relationship of Average Loan Size and Gross Yield. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 Summary and Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . 8O Chapter Page IV EMPIRICAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN RISK ACCEPTANCE AND RATE LEVEL TEST II Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82 Source and Location of Data. . . . . . . . . 83 Demographic Characteristics of Albany, New York and Charleston, West Virginia POpula- tions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 Nature of Data and Structure of Sample . . . 87 Elements of Loan Quality . . . . . . . . . . 88 Application of Credit Scoring System to Test II. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 Expected Score Relationships . . . . . . . . 100 Actual Score Results of Test II . . . . . . 102 Analysis of Credit Factors Included in Score System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 Monthly Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 Personal Characteristics of Applicants . 115 Age . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115 Sex . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 Marital Status. . . . . . . . . . . . 121 Residential Characteristics of Applicants 123 Years in Residence and Home Ownership '123 Telephone Possession. . . . . . . . . 128 Occupational Characteristics . . . . . . 130 Stability of Employment . . . . . . . 130 Nature of Borrower Occupation . . . . 133 Purpose of Loan . . . . . . . . . . . 138 Analysis of Credit Factors Not Included in Score Systems. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141 Size of Loan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142 Amount of Debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145 Monthly Payments . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 Security for Loan. . . . . . . . . . . . 150~ Present, Former, or New Borrower . . . . 153 Race . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155 Possession of Checking Account . . . . . 157 Summary and Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . 157 V EVALUATION OF THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Is the Hypothesis Confirmed? . . . . . . . . 161 Tests of the Hypothesis. . . . . . . . . . . 162 Managerial Policy. . . . . . . . . . . . . 162 Test I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163 vi Chapter Page V Validity of Test I as a Measure of Risk Acceptance and Rate Relationship . . . . 168 Significance of Hypothesis to Intra-firm Risk Discrimination. . . . . . . . . . . . 172 Significance of Findings to Public Policy. . 174 General Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178 APPENDICES. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180 BIBLIOGRAPI-IYO 0 O O 0 O O O 0 C O O O O 0 O O O 0 O O O 198 vii Chart 1.1 LIST OF CHARTS Page Amount of Instalment Credit by Holder, Trends Since 1956. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Top Management View of Risk Standards. . . . . 27 Middle Management View of Risk Standards . . . 33 TOp Management View of Risk-Cost Relationship. 38 TOp Management View of Output Determination. . 41 Relationship Between Gross Yield and Chargeoff Rate for Firm X, Based on Experiences in 27 States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 Relationship Between Gross Yield and Chargeoff Rate for Firm Y, Based on Experiences in 41 States 0 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 65 Relationship Between Gross Yield and Chargeoff Rate for Firm Z, Based on Experiences in 45 States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 Relationship Between Turndown Rate and Gross Yield for Firm X, Based on Experiences in 27 States . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 Relationship Between Turndown Rate and Gross Yield for Firm Y, Based on Experiences in 41 States 0 O O O 0 O 0 O O O O O 0 O O O O O O 70 Expected Relationship Between Score and Finance Rate Level Under Two Score Systems . . . . . 101 Percentage Distribution of Loans Made in Charles— ton and Albany, by Smith Score System. . . . 106 Percentage Distribution of Rejected Applicants in Charleston and Albany, by Smith Score System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 viii Chart Page 4.4 Percentage Distribution of Accepted and Rejected Loan Applicants, for Albany, By Smith Score System . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108 4.5 Actual Relationship Between Score and Finance Rate Levels Under Two Score Systems. . . . . 110 L IST OF EXHIBITS Exhibit .1.1. Outline of Research Design . . . . . . . . . . 24 ix Table 1.1 1.2 LIST OF TABLES Amount and Percentage of Consumer Credit for Selected Years . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Amount and Percentage of Total Debt in U.S. for Selected Years . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Amount and Percentage of Instalment Loans Held by Institutions for Selected Years . . . . . Amount and Percentage of Instalment Credit by Purpose. 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Percentage of Personal Loan Holdings Held by Financial Institutions . . . . . . . . . . . Summary of Regression Equations. . . . . . . . Multiple Correlation Coefficients of Chargeoff Rate and Gross Yield, Average Loan Size, and Per Capita Income by State, for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Multiple Correlation Coefficients of Turndown Rate and Gross Yield, Average Loan Size, and Per Capita Income, by State for Two Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Chargeoff Rates and Gross Yield, by State and for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Turndown Rate with Gross Yield, By State and for Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Chargeoff Rates and Average Loan Sizes, by State for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Turndown Rates with Average Loan Sizes, by State for Two Finance Companies. . . . . . . Page 12 12 14 16 17 59 61 61 63 67 71 72 Table 3.8 3.9 Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Chargeoff Rates and Per Capita Income, by State for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Turndown Rate and Per Capita Income, by State for Two Finance Companies. . . . . . . Multiple Correlation Coefficients of Gross Yield and Average Loan Size and Per Capita Income, by State for Three Finance Companies . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Gross Yield and Per Capita Income, by State and Three Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients of Gross Yield and Average Loan Size by State for Two Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . Selected Social and Economic Characteristics of POpulation in Sample Cities . . . . . . . Relative Importance of Borrower Characteristics as Predictors of Loan Quality. . . . . . . . Risk Elements in Score Systems . . . . . . . . Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants in Albany and Charleston, by Smith Score System Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants in Albany and Charleston, by Consumer Finance Company Score System . . . . . . . . . . . . Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Size of Monthly Income, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Size of Annual Income, for Borrowers and Rejected Applicants. . . . . . Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Age, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi Page 73 75 77 78 79 86 93 100 103 104 112 113 117 Table Page 4.9 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Sex, for Borrowers and Rejected Applicants. . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 4.10 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Marital Status, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . . . . . . 121 4.11 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants, by Years in Present Residence, for Borrowers and Rejected Applicants. . . . 125 44.12 Comparison of Percentage Distributions of Loan Applicants, by Occupancy of Owner Occupied Homes, for Borrowers and Rejected Applicants 127 ‘1-Ll3 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants, by Telephone in Residence, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . 129 4-.Ju4 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants, by Years in Present Occupation, for Borrowers and Rejected Loan Applicants . 132 4° 1—55 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants, by Occupational Groups, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . 136 4‘ J~€S Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants, by intended Purpose of Loans, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . 140 4 . “1—77 Comparison of Percent and Number of Loans by Size of Loans, for Borrowers . . . . . . . . 143 4 “J~EB Comparison of Percent of Loans by Size of Additional Credit, for Borrowers . . . . . . 144 4 ‘:1~S9 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Size of Instalment Debt, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . 146 ‘ :3(D Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applications by Size of Instalment Debt Including Present Loan, for Borrowers. . . . 147 xii Table Page 4.21 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Size of Monthly Payments, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . 149 4.22 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Size of Monthly Payment, in- cluding Present Loan, for Borrowers. . . . . 149 4.23 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loans by Type of Security, for Borrowers . . . . . 151 4.24 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Source--Present, Former, or New Applicant, for Borrowers and Rejected Applicants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154 '4.H25 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Loan Applicants by Race, for Borrowers and Rejected Accounts. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156 4- 26 Comparison of Risk Elements and Credit Scores for Borrowers in Albany, N.Y. and Charleston, W. Va. . . 0 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . O 160 53- 1. Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficient (r) of Chargeoff Rate and Gross Yield, for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164 ES-'22 Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficients (r) of Turndown Rate and Gross Yield, for Three Finance Companies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165 55 ~ :3 Summary of Characteristics of Borrowers and Rejected Loan Applicants in Albany and Charleston, 1964—1965, by Mean Average 167 xiii j, Appendix A (3:3 LIST OF APPENDICES Page Dollar Charges on Different Size Loans Repaid According to Contract at Lawful Maximum Rates of Charge Under 44 Small Loan Laws Arranged by Loan Size Ceiling. . . . . . . . 181 Consumer Finance Companies Supplying Information Used in Study. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182 Simple and Partial Correlation Coefficient Formulas O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Q 183 Risk Element Weights, Smith Credit Score System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184 Mean and Standard Deviation Values of States Experiences for Variables Used in Correlation Analysis, for Three Firms. . . . . . . . . . 186 Comparison of Percentage Distribution of Borrowers, by Bank Account . . . . . . . . . 187 Supplementary Tables to Chapter IV . . . . . . 188 Comparison of Borrower Instalment Debt in Various Income Classifications, for Albany and Charleston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189 Comparison of Borrower Monthly Payments in Various Income Classifications, for Albany and Charleston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190 Comparison of Borrower Residence Stability for Various Income Classifications, for Albany and Charleston . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191 Borrower Monthly Income for Renters and Non- Renters, for Albany and Charleston . . . . . 192 Borrower Resident Stability for Renters and Non-Renters, for Albany and Charleston . . . 193 Monthly Income for Those with Telephone in Residence, for Albany and Charleston . . . . 194 xiv Appendix G7 G8 G9 Residence Stability of Borrowers with Tele- phone in Residence, for Albany and Charleston . . Monthly Income for Present, Former, and New Borrowers, for Albany and Charleston . Borrower Income for Whites and Non—whites, for Albany and Charleston. XV Page 195 196 197 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION General Background Since the early 1900's when Small Loan Laws were enacted through the efforts of the Russell Sage Foundation, consumer credit has played an increasingly important role in our econ- Omy. In 1964, $59.4 billion of instalment consumer credit a rate of . 1 increase greater than that of gross national product. Ap- Was outstanding compared to $11.6 billion in 1949, Proximately 54%of the population owes some form of consumer dEBIDt: to one of many types of financial institutions ranging fITC>Dn a small financial c00perative to a multimillion dollar fjjrliince company. The variety of terms and financial arrange- me’r11:s available at financial institutions is as wide as the per<:es charged for their assortment of services. Some insti— ttltitions, as commercial banks, tend to charge lower prices and grant credit to preferred risk customers, whereas consumer fit"tance companies generally charge higher prices and special- 12 . . . . . Q in serViCing those With a greater degree of risk. 1Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965, p. 472. l ‘- 1'. .I, \c «II I. nth. 2 As is true in most commodities, the greater the cost of producing financial services the higher the equilibrium price. Since commercial banks tend to accept better risks relative to finance companies, their rate of finance charge is somewhat less. However, before drawing definite conclusions between cost and price relationships the historical, moral, and legal restrictions applied to consumer credit must be investigated. Throughout history, society has regarded consumer debt with apprehension and has legally regulated its use.3 Part of this regulation stems from our Judeo-Christian heritage where the virtues of hard work and thrift were the pillars of the Protestant Ethic. While past saving was considered meritorious, borrowing on future income was held in disrespect and disfavor. The attitude toward past saving diverged from the View toward future saving. Loans used primarily for pro— ductive purposes were deemed economically imperative while loans used for immediate consumption reasons were looked upon With askance. As the Western World made greater economic 13rogress and as social mores changed, consumer credit was Elradually regarded as economically necessary and socially ._“‘~ 2 This statement assumes a normal equilibrium price situ- E3”ttion where the demand and supply of funds are somewhat elas- ic. 3 Nugent, Rolf, and Robinson, Louis, Regulation of the ‘§-ll4all Loan Business, Russell Sage Foundation, New YOrk, 1935. 3 desirable. Today, though "productive" loans have gone un- regulated, states still have jurisdiction over the terms of consumer credit. Most states have usury laws permitting a maximum rate of 6% or 7% for all types of credit. Because of the higher costs associated with consumer credit, the usury rate makes it virtually impossible to economically attract sufficient capital to establish consumer credit enterprises. Each state, except for Arkansas, now allows higher rates and encourages firms to enter the small loan market by permitting them to operate under a Small Loan Law, modeled after the Model Small Loan Laws first promolgated by the Russell Sage 4 Foundations in 1916. The impetus for the enactment of enabling legislation to permit consumer credit at higher rates was the "loan shark evil" existing in the late 1800's and early 1900's. It was not uncommon for illegal lenders to charge rates as high as 200% and 300% per annum and often use somewhat brutal collec- tion tactics to attain their goals. The small loan statutes 1"lave contributed to the practical elimination of the "loan 5 ‘3}Iark evil." The social objective of these regulations is t2<> have a freely accessible source of funds at reasonable \ I 4 I . Hubachek, F.B., "The Development of Regulatory Small ian Laws,f Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. VIII, No. 1, later, 1941, pp. 108-138. JC.<:> wi 5 Ibido' pp. 108-138. Im‘ 4 rates; however, to achieve this social goal, the price must be sufficient to induce suppliers of capital to enter the market and earn a reasonable profit. The result of these state regulations is a conglomera- tion of 49 different Small Loan Laws all uniquely different and all allowing diverse maximum rates of charge. The National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws is now work— ing to unify these laws. Nature of the Study The focus of this study is on the relationship between rate levels and risk acceptance standards used by consumer finance companies. While it may be true that consumer finance companies as a whole specialize in servicing higher risk mar— kets, there are Operational differences within this segment of the consumer credit industry. This study is an intra-consumer finance company survey dealing with one segment of the entire consumer credit in- dustry--the consumer finance industry. The consumer credit iUdustry consists of all legal financial institutions grant- ‘iJfig direct and indirect consumer loans and includes commercial 13Einks, sales finance companies, credit unions, retail stores, ‘Eilfixi consumer finance companies. The consumer finance industry ‘i~s a collection of firms granting direct cash loans and oper- 1tLing under the jurisdiction of the Small Loan Law or Industrial , . O“ ..o- -.-h a . t 5 Loan Law within a particular state. The amount of cash loans held by consumer finance companies at the end of 1964 was $4.4 billion, with the 10 major national firms accounting for over 15% of this amount. The constitutional basis for the Small Loan Laws rests on the right of a state to correct a social evil. By permit- ting a certain rate, each state strives to make the terms both economically feasible and socially and morally desirable. The crucial issue is hgw socially desirable and hgw economically feasible. The issue this study hOpes to face is the degree of desirability achieved through a particular rate. Each person or group of persons has its own concept of fairness and desirability and what is fair and conscionable to one is quite the contrary to another. The rate in each state reflects the attitude of its legislative assembly to correct a social evil and insures the provisions of facilities to those who need Credit for consumption purposes. With a particular rate, an entrepreneur must determine the level of expenses he can toler- ate in order to retain a normal profit. The higher the rate lie charges his customer, the more expense he can afford in nnaintaining a reasonable rate of return.‘ Empirical evidence indicates that costs tend to be greater jLIa'higher rate states. In a recent study by Paul E. Smith, \ 6 Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965, p. 472. .ar‘: v-. a... 6 three finance companies charging higher rates also sustained higher levels of Operating expenses in all categories--rent, salaries, etc., compared with two firms charging lower rates.7 The higher rate firms also incurred more bad debt losses, possibly indicating a higher amount of repayment uncertainty within their portfolios. While occupancy costs, investigation costs, salaries, advertising costs, etc., are a large part of the firm's expense, bad debt losses are also a significant portion. As the allowable rate rises, a finance company may be able to tolerate a greater debt loss either by reducing collection efforts or by accepting more repayment uncertainty from the borrower. Whether or not it does and to what extent is the interest of this study. Purpose of the Project The primary purpose of this dissertation is to examine the influence of legal finance charge ceilings on the quality of credit accepted by consumer finance companies. Assuming a positively sloped supply schedule of funds, the most general appriori hypothesis is that significant rate differences alter acceptable risk levels, therefore showing ii- positive relationship between risk and rate. Risk is de- i§lined.as the probability of loan repayment in accordance with \ I Smith Paul, Cost of Providing Consumer Credit, National ‘klreau of Economic Research, New York, 1962, p. 2. the terms of the lender-borrower contract. The test of this assertion relies on a study of manage- ment policies, a regression analysis, and an empirical study of loan applicant quality. The conclusions derived might prove or give evidence to positive, negative, or uncertain relationships. From the empirical study it is hoped to derive a supply schedule of funds available to potential borrowers at various rates. What- ever the conclusions, the goal is to provide a rational, logical method (or approach to a method) for establishing legal finance charge ceilings. The approach of this study is market oriented, suggesting borrower eligibility rather than cost differentials as a key measure of rate structure adequacy. Significance of the Study The apparent need for information concerning those ex- cluded loans due to finance charge ceilings is expressed in a recent bulletin by the National Conference of Commissioners On Uniform State Laws. "The Commissioners on Uniform State Laws have undertaken their consumer credit project at the irequest of the Council of State Governments. . .The Commis- fisioner's project contemplates studies with a view toward (Zomprehensive and simplified legislation on substantially all Eispects of consumer credit trade practices, including disclo- sSure of cost of credit, rate controls or ceilings, the time .n. 8 price doctrine and usury, contract provisions, etc." (under- lining mine). There are two approaches to use when determining an 0p- timum finance charge ceiling.9 One approach is that of setting rates on the basis of the lender's costs. Since the cost per dollar of loan is larger on small loans, higher rates may be justified; as loan sizes becomes larger, however, the fixed expense is spread over more loan dollars and average costs are reduced resulting in lower rates. In the report, The Con- sumer Finance Industgy submitted by the National Consumer Fi- nance Association to the National Commission on Money and Credit, it states that "small loan rates of charge are designed to permit the necessary higher costs of their services, of the more complete investigation, and the special services attached to instalment lending of relatively small sums of money." Professor Paul Smith, in a recent monograph issued by the National Bureau of Economic Research, shows the cost of Providing consumer credit of four major types of financial in- stitutions. His goal was to "ascertain the costscnfdifferent \ T SNational Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State 1¥Ehws, Project on Retail Installment Sales, Consumer Credit, séiflgall Loans and Usury, August 22, 1964, p. 1. It should be noted that a "finance charge" is not the ‘Ssiame as an "interest charge", since interest expense is but tie small portion of consumer credit costs. Lenders need <3 charge a finance charge greater than the interest rate ‘:;" u. 9 types of consumer credit obligations in order to understand the level and structure of the finance rates paid by con- 10 sumers." In an earlier monograph issued by the National Bureau of Economic Research, Ernst A. Dauer also shows evi- ll dence of the relationship between costs and rates. The approach of correlating each finance company's costs with the level of finance charges emphasizes the lender rather than the borrower. In a cost study, the goal is to determine the minimum rate that finance companies must charge in order to earn a fair return. This rate does not indicate that it should be the maximum rate. While the setting of a minimum rate at this level does cover normal operating costs, it does not necessarily cover the risk of loss for those bor- rowers whose financial risk warrants a rate greater than the "cost rate." The second approach to rate setting is to base a rate on the portion of the public that can be served at a given rate. While it may be true that the "cost rate"--let us aSsume 3%F-does provide credit for those who are in the 3% Iiisk class, it does not provide credit for those whose risk -\ W7 10 . . . . Smith, Paul E., Cost of Prov1ding Consumer Credit, IQWEitional Bureau of Economic Research, New YOrk, 1962, . 2. P 11 Dauer, Ernst A., Comparative Operating Experiences ‘5313: Consumer Instalment Financing Agencies and Commercial ‘J§ES§nk§Ll929-4l, National Bureau of Economic Research, :3 Qw York, 1944 . 4.. 10 is greater than 3%. If a maximum rate is set, a private firm cannot serve those who are willing to pay a higher rate be— cause it would not be prOperly matching returns to costs and a fair return. The excessive losses would offset any return on capital. The result of setting a minimum price on capital has the same effect as a minimum wage for labor. If the employee adds value to the firm of only $1.00 per hour and the minimum wage is $1.25 per hour, he will not be hired. Unless he raises his marginal productivity, the worker will remain unemployed. Similarly, with a maximum rate the finance company will not serve the high risk borrower because the risk is not worth the allowed finance charge. By fixing a maximum rate for credit we say that some consumers are not worthy of credit. The prOper or fair rate which provides the greatest bene- fit to the consumer can be determined if we know how many people are "cut out" of the market at any given rate. If this information is available we can reliably say, for example, that a 3% rate will make 20% of the pOpulation ineligible to receive a loan from a consumer finance company. Whether or rust this is desirable is a matter of value judgment. This :jIJdgment is usually made by the state legislatures as they Getermine the finance charge ceilings. Therefore, it is very dLImportant they possess evidence showing the effects of certain A-a' " J"- ,1.- 11 rates upon the pOpulation they represent. Only through a full knowledge of probable effects can an enlightened decision be made. This dissertation uses the second approach to study this problem. By showing the results that rate ceilings have had in the past, we can be more certain of the significance they might have in the future. Importance and Role of Consumer Credit in our Economy The importance of consumer credit in our economy cannot be overemphasized. Since 1939 the amount of consumer credit rose from $7.2 billion to over ten times this amount in 1964. Gross National Product, meanwhile, has increased a little over six times. Instalment credit has increased more than propor- tionately during the past 25 years as it now comprises 77.3% of total consumer credit compared to 62.5% in 1939. Matter of fact, since 1959, the gross national product has increased 3l%--certainly an impressive increase—~but consumer instalment cmedit has increased even more and shows a 49% growth rate. (Table 1.1) While the level of federal, state, and local Sgovernment debt has increased at a very large rate, consumer cZredit has kept pace and now comprises 22% of total govern- fruent, private and consumer credit. (Table 1.2) There are many reasons for this large rate of consumer cI‘edit increase, but probably the most important reasons are 12 TABLE 1.1 AMOUNT AND PERCENTAGE OF CONSUMER CREDIT FOR SELECTED YEARS (Amounts in billions of dollars) 1939 1959 1964 Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Instalment Credit Non-Instal. Credit Total Con- sumer Credit $7.2 100.0% $51.5 100.0% $4.5 62.5% $39.2 76.0% 2.7 37.5 12.3 24.0 Gross National $59.4 77.3% 17.4 22.7 $76.8 100.0% Product $482.8 $634.6 Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965. TABLE 1.2 AMOUNT AND PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL DEBT IN U.S. _ FOR SELECTED YEARS (Amounts in billions of dollars) 1959 Amount Percent IPublic Debt $298 35.2% -I?rivate and Business 372 44.0 COnsumer Debt 175 20 . 8 Total \ Source: $845 100.0% ‘—" Survey of Current Business. 1964 Amount Percent $341 31.2% 511 46.7 242 22.1 $1094 100.0% 13 the changing social attitudes and the incidence of greater economic stability encouraging and conditioning consumers to assume more debt. Since most consumers prefer to purchase products and durable goods rather than rent or lease them, there has been a greater need to finance these larger pur- l2 chases through more debt. Consumer Finance Company Role in Credit Expansion While the level of consumer credit has increased at a growing rate, the proportion served by the consumer finance companies has remained steady. In 1959 and 1964 their rela- tive share of the instalment credit market amounted to 8.5%. Meanwhile the market share of commercial banks and credit unions has increased substantially while retail stores have suffered a strong decline in credit. During the past ten years banks have aggressively competed for consumer credit in contrast to their conservative policies of 25 years ago. (Table 1.3, Chart 1.1) Part of the explanation for the shifts within the -industry is the increased emphasis of commercial banks on Jsetail automobile credit. Personal cash loans have increased in importance since 1959 when they amounted to 24.6% of total 12 Neifeld, M. R., The Personal Finance Business, Harper & Bros., New York, 1933, pp. 189—194. ._‘ .t. 14 TABLE 1.3 AMOUNT AND PERCENTAGE OF INSTALMENT LOANS HELD BY INSTITUTIONS FOR SELECTED YEARS (Amounts in billions of dollars) 1939 1959 1964 Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Commercial Banks $1.1 24.5% $15.2 38.8% $23.9 40.3% Sales Finance Companies 1.2 26.7 10.3 26.3 14.8 24.9 Consumer Fin. Companies* —— -- 3.3 8.5 5.1 8.5 Credit Unions .1 2.2 3.3 8.4 6.5 10.9 Other Financial Ins. .7 15.4 1.4 3.5 1.7 2.9 Retail Outlets 1.4 31.2 5.7 14.5 7.4, 12.5 Total $4.5 100.0% $39.2 100.0% $59.4 100.0% *Consumer Finance Company data included in "Other Fi— Ilancial Institutions" until Sept. 1950. Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965. Jinstalment credit, but rose to 27% in 1964. (Table 1.4) UDhe personal cash loan market has largely been dominated by 1:11e consumer finance industry but it has recently faced Esevere competition from sales finance companies who have ‘51C3ubled their personal cash loan holdings and have increased ‘tllleeir share of the total instalment credit market from 10.1% 15 coma .OU CMOQ HQEDWCOU IIII.... a _ a. .. wcoacb pacwuo mumauso Hflmuwm .OU oUGMCHm mmamm mxcmm amaoumEEo- unmo paws uHmumca Hmuoe moma Noma Homa coma mmma wmma II .. ‘I \A...‘ hmma wmma .N .m .m omma mosz mozmme mmnqom Sm sHommo ezmzqumzH mo azao=< H.H emamc .0 ,.¢ SJEIIop :0 SUCTIITQ 16 TABLE 1.4 AMOUNT AND PERCENTAGE OF INSTALMENT CREDIT BY PURPOSE (Amounts in billions of dollars) 1939 1959 1964 Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Amt. Percent Automobiles $1.5 33.3% $16.4 41.8% $24.5 41.3% Other Consumer Goods 1.6 35.5 10.6 27.1 15.3 25.8 Repair and Modernization .3 6.6 2.8 7.2 3.5 5.9 Personal Cash Loans 1.1 24.6 9.4 23.9 16.1 27.0 Total $4.5 100.0% $39.2 100.0% $59.4 100.0% Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965. to 12.6%. (Table 1.5) Consumer finance companies, meanwhile, have decreased their share of the personal cash loan market from 30.4% to 27.6%. Since many sales finance companies have merged and con- solidated operations with small personal loan companies and Consumer finance companies have expanded their sales finance Ifunctions, a separate distinction between these institutions :Lssnc longer clear cut; therefore, a combined total is useful. TIflhe sales finance companies and consumer finance companies 1:<>ta1 approximately 40%.of the total personal loans outstanding 17 TABLE 1.5 PERCENTAGE OF PERSONAL LOAN HOLDINGS HELD BY FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS 1959 1964 Commercial Banks 34.1% 33.5% Credit Unions 17.6% 20.2% Other Financial Institutions 7.8% 6.1% Consumer Finance Companies 30.4% 27.6% Sales Finance Companies __;g;y% _1246% Total 100.0% 100.0% Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, March, 1965. while the commercial banks have 33% with credit unions holding 20%.of the total. There is no doubt that consumer credit is becoming a nwre important influence in the stability of the economy, since an expansion or contraction of credit can have serious 13 .repercussions. In large measure, the maintenance of ...,, ~— ~..;.. u..- ‘JI H) (In -.‘ ‘A ‘d 'r’ 50 tionship between the independent variables and turndown rates is more restrictive. One firm's data include only their experiences in states with more than 10 offices, since the inclusion of experiences in states with more than 10 offices may bias the conclusion; a firm may alter its short—run credit standards to attain maximum longvrun gains. All three firms conduct lending Operations in approxi- mately the same states and face similar regulatory restrictions. Their experiences with yields, chargeoffs, etc. are similar, but there are a few dissimiliarities. The average state gross yield for Firm X is approximately 3 percentage points less than the average state yield for Firm Y. The gross yield variance is also lower for Firm X. The average chargeoff rate for Firm Y is greater than for the other two firms, tending to substantiate the hypothesis of a positive risk-rate rela- tionship when using aggregate interstate data.2 The average loan size in Firm X is approximately $50 greater than that for Firm Y and $75 greater than Firm Z, partially explaining the lower gross yield experiences of Firm X.(Appendix E) The average turndown rates are very similar for both Firm X and Firm Y. ‘. This View is corroborated in Smith's study of consumer credit costs concluding higher rate companies accept greater Chargeoff rates. Smith, Paul F., Consumer Credit Costs, 1949- ifijfiJ National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1964, p. 25. ..qp-I 01". pg... u...- “no 0 '1‘... .‘5 q m... "V' iv. ’o e... Q" n v... ‘1' ~A ‘v (I‘ 51 The intrafirm data is supplemented with state per capita income figures to provide an overall measure of state risk, although the association of average income and risk is some- what nebulous. Measures of Risk The analysis assumes turndown rates and chargeoff rates are measures of consumer finance company risk acceptance be- havior. These assumptions must be qualified since higher chargeoff rates also reflect different collection methods in addition to loan repayment delinquency. If the same "type" borrower receives credit in two states, for example, but the intensity of collection effort varies, there will be different chargeoff rates because loan repayment then also depends on the lender's repayment "encouragement." However, since branch managers in all states have the same general training from their home office personnel and general loan supervisors, each firm tends to maintain fairly uniform collection policies in all states. Methods of charging off accounts also are con- tingent on the accounting procedures employed in each finance COmpany as some firms "write off" accounts when a borrower is delinquent for 120 days, while others use shorter or longer 'Periods of delinquency. Each branch office in a major finance COmpany, however, uses the same criteria for “charging off" an account. (I) v! -, 'i I. u . ‘3. 1 v I... . _, .. .‘ ‘¢.- IA - " p1 u. u .,_ . . "s 52 In spite of some inconsistency and variation, it is valid to assert that higher chargeoff rates represent more lenient credit policies, although the relationship probably is not proportional. The use of turndown rates as a measure of risk acceptance or rejection is, at best, an inexact measurement of credit policy since many other factors affecting this ratio. Risk differences in the general pOpulation affect turndown rates because more peOple would be rejected for credit in areas where the risk level is lower. On the other hand, if wealthier people live in a particular finance company market area, re- jection rates would be lower. Other important and influencing factors as population levels, employment stability, debt and loan repayment attitudes, and the general economic position of the community also influence rejection patterns. The com- petitive nature of the state and local markets is also impor- tant in situations where banks, credit unions, and sales finance companies aggressively compete with consumer finance companies. Legal regulations on all forms of financial institutions also affect finance companies practices. Since all of these factors influence the nature of consumer finance company markets, turn- down rates are less reliable indicators of credit standard Variability. 53 Methods of Measuring Association The correlation analysis attempts to statistically hold certain variables constant in order to isolate the influence of finance charges on turndown and chargeoff rate levels. If other factors are held relatively constant, the measurement of these associations is useful in suggesting a risk and rate relationship. The regression equations show chargeoff rates and turn- down rates as the independent or explained variables and gross yield, average loan size, and per capita state income as the independent or explaining variables. The analysis is extended further with a correlation analysis of the relation- ship between gross yield and non-risk measuring variables to lend insight into rate structure patterns. While multiple regression coefficients do not show causal relationships, they do provide a measure of association among variables, either causal or resulting. Since gross yield and per capita income figures are uncontrollable by the lender,3 the relationship of these variables with the depend— ent variables suggests a causal relationship since chargeoff and turndown rates are more flexible and controllable. In all cases the simple, partial, and multiple coeffi- cients are calculated to determine the coefficients of x 3 Assuming loan sizes do not change and the maximum rate is charged. 54 correlation (r) and the coefficients of association (A). The simple correlations relate one independent variable with a dependent variable, while the partial coefficients measure association by considering one independent variable and holding one or more other independent variables constant. The multiple correlation coefficients indicate the influence of all the independent variables associated with the depend- ent variables. They are very difficult to interpret because the addition of two or more variables makes it difficult to distinguish which variable is more closely related. For this reason a partial correlation coefficient is more useful. The coefficients of association (A) measure the percentage of dependent variable standard deviation "explained" by the 4 independent variable(s). (Appendix C) Expected Relationship between Gross Yield and Chargeoff Rate There most likely is a positive relationship between gross yields and chargeoff rates since loan supervisors indi- Cate they are somewhat flexible in their credit standards. “Haapter II) As discussed earlier, it seems economically SOLnnd for firms to accept higher credit losses when charging hi4gfuar rates because a higher marginal revenue per loan permits 4 Ekeblad, Frederick A., The Statistical Method in Busi— £§E§§§,. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, 1962, p. 574. fZekial’ Mordecai, and Fox, Karl A., Methods of Correlation ‘EEZ__JE§?g£ession Analysis, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1959, p0 532. 55 them to accept higher marginal costs at Optimum output levels. Of course, additional expected risk assumption loss is not the only expense consideration since salaries, rents, and other expenses vary geographically. The influence of factor costs is not included in the regression equation. Expected Relationship between Gross Yield and Turndown Rates There probably is a negative relationship between turn- down rates and gross yields since firms charging higher rates may accept a greater percentage of applicants as borrowers. If lenders accept more risk in higher rate states their turn— down rates may not vary because of a greater or smaller pro- portion of "riskier" applicants in the loan market area. Turndown rates are also affected by the degree of financial institution competition in each loan market area. Expected Relationship between State Per Capita Income and Chargeoff Rates It is doubtful whether there is a strong relationship between state per capita income and chargeoff rates since each finance company asserts that it accepts the maximum amount of risk at a minimum acceptable rate, regardless of the state income level. (Chapter II) However, it is possible that companies accept a fixed level of credit in all states and extend little effort to secure additional borrowers once this level is attained. In higher income states lenders may a nun V a. .40" or. a r-u '\ (1| 56 sustain increased loan balances, and economies of scale may influence them to sustain higher chargeoff rates. Each of these possibilities could cause chargeoff rates to be corre- lated with state income. These possibilities are doubtful, however, and suggest only possible rather than probable policies. Expected Relationship between State Per Capita Income and Turndown Rates It seems likely that states with higher per capita in- comes have relatively lower turndown rates, although rate structure may simultaneously influence rejection levels. If borrower income is a measure of risk, then finance companies are rational in accepting a greater percentage of higher income applicants, other factors being equal. Expected Relationship between Average Loan Size and Risk Acceptance Most consumer credit cost studies infer an inverse relae tionship between average loan size and the amount of borrower risk. A recent study showing data accumulated from one state indicates a relatively high inverse correlation coefficient 5 of -055 between loan size and chargeoff rate. Part of the reason for the more favorable experience with larger loans 5 Comiskey, Eugene E., A Study of Loan Cost Behavior In Consumer Finance Companies, unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1965. 57 15 the tendency of present borrowers to be more readily accepted for them since their creditworthiness has been confirmed. In addition, credit investigation of applicants seeking larger loans is more thorough and complete. Expected Relationship of Variables Indirectly Associated with Hypothesis The purpose of Small Loan Legislation is to fulfill con- sumer capital needs because usury rates are inadequate to attract sufficient funds. Rate is not the only important determinate of credit availability, however, as Small Loan Legislation limits the maximum amount a borrower can obtain from one finance company. Some legal loan size limits, while designed to prevent a borrower from going into too much debt have not been adequate to fulfill the growing demand of bor- rowers with higher incomes who want more credit. In a large sense, loan size ceilings are interdependent with rate levels since states allowing larger loans also tend to allow lower average rates. A full explanation and description of this relationship is not the object of this study, but one should be aware of the existence and influence of loan size ceilings. For a more complete discussion of the need for higher loan size ceilings see: Phelps, Clyde W., "Consumer Finance Charges II," The Journal of Marketing, July, 1952, pp. 22-36. Kawaja, Michael, "On the Inflexibility of Small Loan Rates and Loan Size Ceilings," Personal Finance Lawfguarterly Report, Spring, 1965, pp. 57—59. 58 A statistical correlation of rate levels and average loan sizes balances shows a partial indication of this inter— action. Since both rate ceilings and loan size ceilings are determined by law, they show the extent of legislative aware- ness of this relationship. These two factors in a sense, are mutually determined by legislatures who try to establish a rate ceiling and loan size ceiling capable of serving the borrowing community without allowing lenders to earn exorbitant profits.. Lenders allowed to grant larger loans can afford to charge lower rates since a large portion of unit costs is relatively fixed and therefore lenders are concerned with the amount of revenue rather than the gate of revenue for them to breakeven and earn a fair return. Obviously, the breakeven revenue needed for a $500 loan is not five times greater than the revenue needed for a $100 loan. The breakeven relation- ship between rate and loan size is not linear. This is accom- modated with the multibracket rate structure where incremental revenues decrease as loan sizes increase, but it is doubtful whether the decreasing rates of revenue are equal to decreasing rates of cost. Because of these relationships, there probably is an inverse correlation between average loan sizes and aver- age gross yields. In addition, a correlation of state per capita income and finance charge levels is measured to partially explain 59 the logic of state finance charge ceilings. The most likely relationship is inverse, since each higher income state would tend to allow a higher loan size ceiling which, in turn, is associated with a lower average yield. A summary of the regression equations used in this chapter is shown in Table 3.1. TABLE 3.1 E The variables and their symbols are: A = Chargeoff rate B = Turndown rate C = Gross Yield D = Average Loan Size E = Per Capita Income The multiple correlation equations are: Dependent Variables Independent Variables Table A = C,D,E 3.2 B = C,D,E 3.3 C = D,E 3.10 The partial correlation equations are: Dependent Variables Independent Variables Table A = C1D,E 3.4 B = C1D,E 3.5 A = DlC,E 3.6 B = DlC,E 3.7 A = ElC,D 3.8 B = ElC,D 3.9 C = ElD 3.11 C = DlE 3.12 Indicates variables held constant. 6O Empirical Evidence Multiple Correlations The multiple correlation coefficients shown on Tables 3.2 and 3.3 indicate regression coefficients (r) when chargeoff rate or turndown rate is correlated with all of the independ- ent variables-—gross yield, average loan size, and state per capita income. Only two companies reported their turndown ratios but each supplied all of the other data. Correlation coefficients are computed for each company separately and for the combined experiences of all the firms. The multiple correlation of the combined experiences for the three companies indicates a coefficient of .47 when corre— lating chargeoff rate with the independent variables. (Table 3.2) The coefficient is not unusually high but shows that all or some of the independent variables are associated with charge- off rates. The relationship among companies differs as shown by the multiple correlation coefficient for Firm X which is twice that of Firm Y and 30 percent greater than Firm Z's coefficient. The coefficients of association (A) show an even greater coefficient spread as the A of .23 for Firm X is four times that of Firm Y and about twice the A.of Firm Z. The relationship between turndown rate and the three variables for the combined experience of the two companies is not as strong as the chargeoff relationship and there is 61 greater inconsistency in individual company experience. Firm X shows a multiple correlation coefficient of .75 compared to the r of .25 for Firm Y. Firm Z did not report turndown data. (Table 3.3) TABLE 3.2 MULTIPLE CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS OF CHARGEOFF RATE AND GROSS YIELD, AVERAGE LOAN SIZE, AND PER CAPITA INCOME BY STATE, FOR THREE FINANCE COMPANIES A.= C,D,E Coefficient of Coefficient of Correlation (r) Association (A) Firm X .64 .23 Firm Y .32 .06 Firm Z .47 .13 Firms X,Y,Z .47 .13 TABLE 3.3 MULTIPLE CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS OF TURNDOWN RATE AND GROSS YIELD, AVERAGE LOAN SIZE, AND PER CAPITA INCOME, BY STATE FOR TWO FINANCE COMPANIES B = C,D,E Coefficient of Coefficient of Correlation (r) Association (A) Firm X .75 .36 Firm Y .25 .04 Firms X,Y .21 .03 62 Relationship between Chargeoff Rate and Gross Yield A simple correlation analysis of chargeoff rate and gross yield shows an r of .47 for the combined experiences of the three companies, indicating a fairly strong relationship among variables. (Table 3.4) These data indicate that lenders in states with higher gross yields experience higher chargeoff levels, although the simple correlation figure does not tell whether yield alone is associated with chargeoff rate because other variables are allowed to vary. The simple correlation suggests that yield levels are an important influence on chargeoff rates when other variables may actually be more influential. The partial correlation coefficient of .44 indicates the direct influence or association of yield on chargeoff rates when holding other variables included in the analysis relatively constant. In effect, the .44 partial coefficient indicates that gross yield "explains" 10 percent of the chargeoff rate standard deviation. The simple and partial correlation coefficients are mod~ erately high for each of the three firms with Firm Z showing the highest simple correlation and Firm Y showing the largest partial coefficient. The data used to correlate Firm Z's experiences exclude certain observations thought to be non- representative of company policy. Chart 3.3 shows a simple relationship between yield and chargeoff rate with three observations clearly out of line. When all of the experiences 63 are considered, the partial correlation coefficient is -.15, an obvious refutation of the hypothesis. While it is always convenient to exclude certain data to obtain higher coeffici— ents, the observations in this instance are too extreme to justify their inclusion. The data from Firm X include only those obtained from states where 10 or more branch offices are located since their inclusion would less likely be repre— sentative of overall company policy. When all of Firm X's experiences are included, however, the partial correlation coefficient between chargeoff rate and gross yield is only .04, indicating no relationship. It does not appear this relationship is representative of overall company behavior because in smaller Operations, firms make short-run adjust- ments to attain longer-run goals. Therefore, the data would be biased if they include these shorter—run experiences. The data in Table 3.4 and Charts 3.1, 3.2 and 3.3 reveal the strong simple and partial relationships. TABLE 3.4 SIMPLE AND PARTIAL CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS OF CHARGEOFF RATES AND GROSS YIELD, BY STATE AND FOR THREE FINANCE COMPANIES A = ClDE Simple Partial Partial Correlation Correlation Coefficient of Coefficient (r) Coefficient (r) Association (A) Firm X .38 .26 -04 Firm Y .28 .31 .05 Firm Z .41 .28 .05 Firms X,Y,Z .47 .44 .10 64 Xmm Rom .xwm wm oawflw mmono RON Xflm AXVNN nRON \\\ mm..ucm. UHMMOOU c. ufiumawuu0n mMB¢Bm hm ZH mmvzmHmmmxm ZO Qmmfim .X ZMHm mom m9¢m hmOvam/NEO szw BMHW mmOMO mezBmmm mHmmZOHBfimm Hom EEO XH RN fim sggoaBJqu iueoxed 65 R UHOHN mmOHO mmedem He 2H mmuzmHmmmxm zo Ommcm mmomomummuo moon» msHUOHU new ucmaoflm moo coflueamuuou X0 50. "ucmfloammmoo coflueaouuou mmeun.oum soemmaumnv musdom OONH "cam: cosmoaumnv Rem Smamfim mmOUm EBHEm Mm .Mz¢m4¢ QZ< ZOEmflAMdflU ZH Il..| .832 mass mzcoq no 2398233 mocezmommm meagre III coummaumno . . queoxed 107 an xaccmmmc mom I Ewummm ucaom mo c0aumsmamxm HOmv Auuommu Emumhm muoom nuaEm so mucaom oc XV ccaa. coma ccna ccma ccma ccaa ccm ccb ccm _ lHl o \\ Rm W“Y\ Xoa \\ mama m mucaom Re 5.56.... . acmnac mucaom acma "8mm wannad “\‘ Xmm musaom mm¢ u.>mn.©um cocmoaumgc \\\\ musaom mama "smmz cocmwanmsv , Rom hamnam zmsmwm mmoom maazm am .Mz¢m4¢ 924 209mmamOIHOO® O.H boa m.© m.® mofi m.® OOOGIHoom m.m h.¢ m.w mom m.OH O.NH OOOQIHOOB m.m N.© m.OH H.0H bow mom OOOthoow m.OH O.¢H ®.OH H.MH NomH m.ON OOOQIHOOm w.mH N.©H m.m m.HH m.NN m.ON OOOmIHOO¢ N.¢N N.®N ®.m m.OH homH 0.0H OOOfiIHOOm m.NN mowH ¢.h m.h ®.OH 5.0 OOOMIOOON max: .86 $93 as .m aoé am; 6.68:0 w coumwaumso hcmfldd coummaumzu mamaad coummaumno mcmnad msoosa mucsooum cmuomnmm *QOHUMasmom amumcww mHOBOnuom aMDCC¢ mBZ¢UHamm< DMBUHbmm 92¢ mMMSOMMOm mom .mZOUZH Q¢DZZ< m0 MNHm Mm mBZa23 wumum Cato .mcmoa usmEamumGH Hmesmcoo .©a>mn .3 .mcannom «monsom« 117 II ~.Na N.Na II II m.ma N.aa .>mn .Uum I- o.mm m.mm m.am m.mm c.aa «.me whencmmz Xc.cca Xc.cca Kc.cca Xc.cca Xc.cca fic.cca xc.cca amuOB o ~.m m.m o o o m. uuommm oz m.a N.¢ c.¢ m.ha c.5N m.aa m.h uw>OIcc m.v m.m m.m v.> a.m c.m m.ca mmImm m.> m.m m.m m.m a.ca >.aa c.aa emlcm c.ca «.5 m.m a.ca c.m N.ma m.ma vamv N.Na m.m c.aa c.aa a.m «.ma m.ma celcv m.¢a c.aa m.m ¢.Na c.m m.ma c.ma mmImm m.ha c.m m.ca n.aa h.m 5.0a «.ma «Mlcm m.ma m.ma c.5a m.ca a.m c.aa m.ca mmlmm Xa.aa Xm.¢m fic.mm Xm.ca $a.m Xm.n 0.5 VNION mumc coumoaumnv hsmflad soummanmno acmna¢ coummaumno mcmndfi whom» a.mcannom mpcsooom cwuowflmm #COaumasmom amumcmw mnmzounom ca wmfi mBZDOUUd Omeumbmm 02¢ mMflBOmmom mom .mwd Nm mBZac2 ouwum OaLO .mcmoa OCOEamuwcH uoESmcou .Ua>mo .3 .mcannom “mousom * .muuooom wOmcmO mo smwuom .m.c "mousom # Xc.cca Kc.cca Xc.cca Xc.cca $0.00a Kc.cca Xc.cca amuoe a.m c.mm m.mm m.w m.c m.¢a m.ma mOOOCMaamUmaS N.n m.ma m.ma a.c a.n c.¢a m.ma muwxuoz caonmmsom pom moa>uom m.cm c.©a m.ma m.ma N.ma c.aa m.ma muoxuoz postnam pom mm>aumummo c.aa m.ca c.ma ¢.m N.n m.ma m.ma mumuonma n.mm m.c c.v m.ma m.ma m.m c.> muwxuoz pmuocax . Ucm cmewuom .cmEmuwmuO m.m N.m m.ca m.m c.w >.aa c.ma muwxuoz mmamm N.m m.m n.m m.m n.ca m.m m.¢ muoxuoz couocax can amoauwao N.m m.a s.m ~.o m.m n.o m.m muouoauoouo mamm o.m k.~ a.ca o.m ~.o m.k mapooaooo .muommomz $m.ma Xm.m Xm.v $¢.ma Xm.ma Xm.m XO.N mumxuoz conceax com aooacnooe .aocoammmmoum mumo coumwau030 >cmfla¢ coummaHMLU wanna< couwmaumfiv >cmna¢ I c: .mcaflflom mucoooom Uwuownwm #:OHHMaDQOm amuwcww muw3ouuom Ohm Hmcoflummsooo mszoooom III mommawmmmwwm.wm .msz cmeomomm c24 mmmsommom mom ma.v mqmce 137 a guide, there appears to be greater risk acceptance patterns in Charleston, although the difference is not substantial. The tendency for lenders in Charleston to accept more risk and also turndown more risk is not verified in the rejected applicant statistics. In both cities approximately 26% of the rejected applicants are "white collar" workers, while over 50% The incidence of rejected applicants not are "blue collar”. reporting their occupations is over 20% in both cities, so their analysis is not complete. The percentage in the mis- cellaneous category includes those persons unemployed or receiving unemployment compensation. The Albany and Charleston occupational experiences differ from those observed by Robbins in his 1950-1951 data since only 24% of the borrowers in his sample were classified as 34 "white collar" compared to over 33% in the two city sample. A 1958 survey by the National Consumer Finance Association confirms Robbins' findings and shows little change in the 35 trend of borrower occupation. The discrepancy between the national averages and the Albany and Charleston experiences lies in the nature of occu- pants found in each city. Since both Albany and Charleston Ibid., p.58. 5 National Consumer Finance Assoc1ation, The Consumer inance Industry, A monograph prepared for the Commission on cney and Credit, Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 962, p. 67. {‘U'L‘l‘fiv-I-..‘ 1\1'l ”A 5' 138 are the capitol cities of their states, there tends to be a greater prOportion of clerical and professional workers com- pared to those in an "average" industrial city. Approximately 44% of the general pOpulation in Albany are "white collar" workers and 49% of the workers in Charleston are classified into this category. This differs from the national average 36 of less than 40%. Since a greater percentage of population \C'l'fl‘lfln’ful " ..’ is "white collar" it is only reasonable that a larger per- centage would be found in the loan portfolios of consumer {Min W' ' .‘I"I‘.4H {I finance companies. The significant part of this data is the similarity of the experiences in the two cities, even if there is dissimilarity between the national averages and the Albany and Charleston experiences. The latter is explained by differences in their loan markets relative to those in other cities. While there is a 6% difference between the occupational status of borrowers in the two cities, the difference is too small to be considered as solid evidence of differences in aversion or tendency to accept risk. Puppose of the loan Very few consumer finance company credit scoring systems Dnsider the intended use of the loan as a means of predicting 36U.S. Bureau of Census Reports. 139 ride butnwst credit managers use this information in deter- mhungvmedmr or not to grant credit. Smith analyzed the lossgnprfllities of each loan purpose classification and asmnts Hume applying for loans to use for debt consolida- 37 tioncntnwdical purposes are riskier applicants. Durand's statistux;are not homogeneous enough for him to draw any strongcxnmflusions regarding the risk aspects of each loan purpose category. The data gathered from the Albany and Charleston lenders show approximately 18%.of the borrowers in each city obtained credit to consolidate present debt, while 21% of the borrowers in Albany obtained credit to pay for current expenses compared to twice this amount in Charleston. Because of the arbitrary assignment of loan purpose by the interviewer and researcher, it is hazardous to place great reliance on the data. For instance, "current expenses" can mean many things and can applyrtxDInost of the other classifications. Table 4.16 shows a fair similarity between the experiences in both cities except for the current expense category. of the data and the similarity of the data which is available it is difficult to draw any conclusions regarding risk patterns Dased on loan purpose. It: is; iJiteresting to note the greater incidence of rejected L37 Snuitli, pp.cit., p. 334. Because of the unreliability Inc—r- 'i-‘v'i. 140 $3.... . HZ... 31.315.11.5'451.» .53fi5dtu .xoonumow muomm mucosam .am .m ..U.Q soumcanmmz .mcma .soaumaUOmm< mucosam nmEOmGOU aMCOaumz "00m .moma .mmoawmo cnme ca mHOBOHHOQ Eonm sumo soaumaUOmmd mocmcam umEsmcoo amsoaumz "mouooma $0.cca fic.cca Xc.cca So.cca $0.cca amuoe o.ma v.m o m.m m.n uncoou oz o.k~ 6.0m o.s~ o.mm m.ae momoouoo porno m.a m. o.m m.~ n.m weapoou oaonomsom m.m m.aa o.m m.m m.m mmoaamaouoo meow m.cm m.vm c.aa m.m c.m muammwu o momsousm oaanoeouzfl s.a m.m o.m m.o m.¢a omomoxm ooapmoooo o Goapmom> .ao>mna Xm.mm Xm.vm fic.m¢ $o.na fim.ma coaumoaaOmcoo undo soumoaumnu acmnad amumo smoz coumoaumsu >cmfla¢ cmoa mo muCSOUUM Owuomnmm mHO3OHHOm mmomusm ; omozmszH mm .mdeoaqmms meZpooo< omsomomm QZ< mmMSOmmom m om .wmaoq mo mmomma zaoq mo onscmHmech moaszmommm mo zcmammmzcc 141 applicants who intend to use funds for debt consolidation and automobile expense, since approximately 50% of the turndowns needed funds for these purposes compared to 27% for the bor- rowers. Part of the reason is because auto dealers probably have first referred the prospective buyers to a commercial bank where they have been rejected and when they apply at a finance company they are rejected there also. Many credit men are wary of a "merchant referrel". Comparing the Albany and Charleston experiences with the national average, we find fewer borrowers in these two cities using funds for debt consolidation and more using the funds for current expenses. The sample also includes a greater pro- portion using funds for automobile purposes. The 1950-1951 study of Robbins using data from 14 consumer finance companies 38 reveal experiences similar to the NCFA data. The NCFA data show 48% Of borrowers Obtain funds for debt consolidation, a definite increase since 1958 and a distinct difference from 39 There is no doubt that the Albany and Charleston findings. a large part of this discrepancy can be explained by overlap— ping groupings of data. Analysis of Credit Factors Not Included in Score Systems The Smith and Consumer Finance Company systems use only 38Robbins, op.cit. p. 87. 39National Consumer Finance Association, Finance Facts 'earbook, 1965, p. 51. 142 8 and 10 borrower characteristics and do not consider an applicant's financial position nor the amount of credit a borrower obtains. Since there is an $800 maximum loan size limit in each state, the average loan size should be similar if companies are equally restrictive. Other characteristics as possession of a checking or savings bank account, race, or new borrower, and the security whether a present, former, of the note are credit factors not included in the score sys- tem. Therefore, in order to complete the study of relative risk in each sample, it is necessary to compare these character- istics. Size of Loan. Table 4.17 indicates there is very little difference in the number of loans according to loan size. A firm charging a lower finance rate may be more reluctant to grant smaller sized loans, (depending on the structure of rates, of course), but there is little evidence of this being the case. The average loan size is $587 in Albany and is somewhat lower in Charleston-—-but the difference is too small to imply different risk acceptance patterns. Table 4.17 indicates the total loan size for each borrower while Table 4.18 shows the additional credit extended to borrowers. Since a large pro- >ortion of borrowers already have credit at the consumer firm ompany and are classified as present borrowers (about 80%) , 1e applicant is frequently requesting additional credit up f... hLIU.‘ s- “a...“ ." '5' ”It, l-fi ' 141.111.! '11.. 143 TABLE 4. l7 COMPARISON OF PERCENT AND NUMBER OF LOANS BY SIZE OF LOANS, FOR BORROWERS 'ng—m—f-‘NT-T‘ 449...... ;-. 1 m ==== Amount Albany Robbins* Charleston of loan NO. % data NO. % $0-$50 1 .2 7.6% 2 . 3 51-100 4 . 7 14.09 11 1.8 101-150 12 2.0 13.42 25 4.2 151-200 18 3.0 12.30 17 2.8 201-300 48 8.0 29.59 53 8.8 301-400 60 10.0 19_04 69 11.5 401-500 59 9.8 45 7. 5 501-750 142 23.7 2.33 101 16.8 751-800 256 42.7 1.36 277 46.2 NO report & Misc. 0 0 .26 0 0 Total 600 100.0% 100.0% 600 100.0% Mean $587 $577 *Source: Robbins, W. David, Consumer Instalment Loans, Ohio State University, 1955, p. 41. It is assumed Robbins' data refer to the total amount of credit. to the $800 limit. Table 4.18 shows that in both Albany and Charleston approximately 30% Of the borrowers obtained addi— tional credit of $100 or less and approximately 10—12% of the borrowers obtained new credit of $500-$800. The average loan size of $587 in Albany is comparable to the $577 in Charleston. It is interesting to compare the frequency distributions If the sample with those derived by Robbins based on 1950—1951 CDMPARISON OF PERCENT OF LOANS BY SIZE OF 144 TABLE 4.18 ADDITIONAL CREDIT, FOR BORROWERS State University, Robbins' data refer to the total amount of credit. lending experiences. .portjrn1<3f larger loans are made today than 15 years ago when I Ammufi: Robbins' data* of loan Albany (Total Credit) Charleston $0-$fl3 18.5% 7.61% 6.8% 51-100 12.0 14.09 22.5 101-150 15.7 13.42 18.7 151-200 11.3 12.30 8.5 201-300 17.7 29.59 18.0 301-400 10.5 19.04 11.0 401—500 2.3 2.33 4.0 501-750 8.3 1.36 7.0 751-800 3.7 .26 3.5 No report & Misc. 0 -- 0 Total 100.0% 100.00% 100.0% *Source: Robbins, W. David, Consumer Instalment Loans, Ohio 1955, p. 41. It is assumed It is clear that a much greater pro— legal loan ceilings and general income levels were lower. $500 in 1951. and $750 in total credit, While 60-70% of all loans in the 1964 sample are between $500 only 3.5% of all loans were over Loan sizes are much larger today than before. ‘40 Robbins, op.cit., p. 41. iata refer to the total amount of credit. It is assumed that Robbins' (t-‘u IF" I. a» ‘ s 145 Based on total loan sizes and additional credit extended, it is clear that very little differences in lending practices between offices in these two cities and consequently there is little justification for alleging risk acceptance differences on the basis of loan size variations. Amount of Debt The score system does not measure the effect of present financial consumer instalment obligations on a prospective borrower's ability to repay a loan. While Smith and Durand both conclude that financial characteristics are unreliable predictors of loan repayment, it is still useful to compare differences between borrowers in both communities for if borrowers in Charleston, for instance, have a greater amount of debt, it is fair to assume they are riskier than Albany borrowers. Therefore, there would be a partial confirmation of the hypothesis. As shown previously, credit managers con- sider financial position very carefully when determining bor- rower loan eligibility. (Table 4:2) The data in Table 4.19 show some similarity between the financial obligations of borrowers in Albany and Charleston. In both cities, approximately 50% of the borrowers have instal- ment debts exceeding $1000 and about 15% of borrowers have debts less than $250. The mean debt level is somewhat higher in Vharleston by about $375 and this amount is significant. a ’_n ;'-' "d" WnMuHA-‘wLafi‘ n In: (5.. i 146 TABLE 4.19 COMPARISON OF PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF LOAN APPLICANTS BY SIZE OF INSTALMENT DEBT, FOR BORROWERS AND REJECTED ACCOUNTS Debt Borrowers Rejected accounts Albany Charleston Albany Charleston $0 3.0% 2.5% 15.2% 14.0% 1-100 2.8 2.2 6.2 10.5 101-250 7.0 5.8 11.0 12.5 251-500 14.7 8.5 17.0 12.2 501-750 10.2 11.0 9.3 7.7 751-1000 10.8 9.3 11.2 6.7 1001-1500 17.8 14.2 10.7 9.0 1501-2000 13.3 14.3 6.5 5.8 2001-over 20.4 32.2 6.8 10.2 No Report 0 0 6.2 11.6 Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% Mean $1306 $1681 $782 $816 Not only is it significant when considered singularly but it is meaningful when comparing it to the general population in- come level of each city. The median annual income is $5616 for a borrower in Albany and $5364 for a borrower in Charles- ton. (Table 4.7) Instalment debt as a percentage of annual income is 31% in Charleston and 23% in Albany, implying a ”borrowing power premium" of 8% of annual income for Charleston borrowers. If the 31% ratio is applied to the Albany income :here would be an additional $430 of borrowing power available or these borrowers. The data in Appendix G.l further show r‘- MEL. "ran-u“ no".-c‘ L‘l v '...‘.u . - . . 147 .hat in every income classification borrowers in Charleston .ave more instalment debt. If borrower demand does not vary oetween the two cities and there is no presumption there does, then lenders are likely to assume more risk in Charleston where the finance rate ceiling is higher. This may be the result of lenders' overtly recognizing that the rate differentials allow them more lending power, but increased competitive pressure is the most likely explana— tion. Assuming a fairly competitive market, each lender will extend credit to those who will afford him a fair return. TABLE 4.20 COMPARISON OF PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF LOAN APPLICATIONS BY SIZE OF INSTALMENT DEBT INCLUDING PRESENT LOAN, FOR BORROWERS Debt Albany Charleston $0 0% 0% 1—100 . 75 .25 101-250 4.00 3.25 251—500 9. 75 8.25 501-750 10. 75 7.25 751-1000 12.75 10.25 1001-1500 20. 50 19.00 1501-2000 15.00 14. 75 2001-0ver 26. 50 37.00 No Report 0 0 Total 100.00% 100.0% Source: Based on a sample of 400 accounts in each city. .._‘-__..‘_. ”1::9- 5.x 5. Sr '5. 'T‘u‘ - "IS-7' 148 The tendency for lenders in Charleston to extend credit to applicants with higher debt levels is verified with the data shown in Table 4.20 where 71% of Charleston borrowers had debt of $1000 or more after the new loan was granted as com— pared to 61% in Albany. The difference in the debt level of rejected accounts confirms the observations of borrower debt was: level. Monthlnyayments HQLCAA‘QM. 1.; on‘. 1L". _ . ‘. The average monthly payment for borrower in Charleston 1 is greater than in Albany, since the mean monthly payment be- fore the new credit extension is $77 in Albany and $96 in Charleston, compared to $89 and $102 when looking as the "after new loan" monthly payment position. As Table 4.21 shows,approximately 32% of the borrowers make payments of $100 or more in Albany, while 46% of the borrowers in Charles- ton make this size of payment. The "before new loan" position shown in Table 4.21 indicates there is a greater prOportion of rejected applicants with high monthly payments in Charleston than in Albany, since 9.5% of the applicants already have $100 or more of monthly payments while approximately 10% more Charleston applicants have this size of obligation. The same tendencies are shown from the "after new loan" data in Table 4.22. In every income classification, borrowers in Charleston have higher monthly payments. (Appendix Table G.2) COMPARI 149 TABLE 4.21 SON OF PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF LOAN APPLICANTS BY SIZE OF MONTHLY PAYMENTS, FOR BORROWERS AND REJECTED ACCOUNTS Monthly Borrowers Rejected accounts Payment Albany Charleston Albany Charleston $0 4.0% 3.0% 20.0% 12.0% 1-25 13.7 9.0 9.5 12.0 26-50 21.7 13.7 13.7 17.2 51—75 15.5 17.0 11.8 14.2 76-100 18.7 14.3 6.7 12.0 101-150 16.8 22.8 6.2 12.9 151-200 7.0 12.8 2.5 5.8 201-over 2.6 5.8 1.6 2.5 No Report 0 1.6 28.0 11.4 Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% Mean $77.39 $95.88 $42.73 $46.70 TABLE 4.22 COMPARISON OF PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF LOAN APPLICANTS BY SIZE OF MONTHLY PAYMENTS, INCLUDING PRESENT LOAN FOR BORROWERS* Monthly Albany Charleston Payment $0 .25% 0% 1—25 10.25 7.02 26—50 21.75 13.28 51—75 16.50 19.80 75-100 18.50 13.03 101-151 21.50 25.06 151-200 8.50 14.54 201-over 2.75 7.27 No Report 0 0 Total 100.00% 100.0% Mean. $89 $102 *Based on a sample of 400 accounts in each city. 3 7 i...‘éJ 150 There is a greater proportion of rejected applicants who did not report their obligation in Charleston, so it is difficult to say what effect information derived from these applicants would have. The monthly payment is also affected by the maxi- mum legal maturity allowed in each state. A borrower may have 24 months to repay a loan in New York, while in West Virginia, he is allowed 30 months. The longer the maturity of the note, g the smaller will be the monthly payments. g In any case, both the general debt and monthly payment é levels are higher in Charleston than in Albany and tend to % confirm the risk-rate hypothesis. Security for Loan Some credit managers allege that the type of security offered by the lender is an important ingredient of risk since a liquid and assessible type of security assures a larger prob- ability of eventual loan repayment. While finance companies do not like to repossess goods that are generally unsalable, they sometimes do repossess items when there is no other re- payment solution. During the past few years, the emphasis has been for fewer tangible goods to be used as security items and for more unsecured or signature notes. According to a National Consumer Finance Association Study, only 15.7% of loans granted in 1939 were unsecured compared to 28.9% in 151 41 1962. Robbins study of 13 consumer finance companies shows 42 that in 1950 and 1951 approximately 25% of loans were unsecured. (Table 4.23) (It might be noted, in contrast, that 65% of com- mercial bank loans and only 2.6% of loans from credit unions were unsecured.) TABLE 4.23 COMPARISON OF PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OF LOANS fi BY TYPE OF SECURITY, FOR BORROWERS ; Robbins' i Security Albany Charleston NCFA* study# 5 Motor Vehicle 18.0% 13.0% 12 .0% 14. 7% 1' Household Goods 43.4 50.6 44.8 43.2 Unsecured Note 31.0 30.2 28.9 25.6 Comaker 7.0 5.7 2.2 4.2 Other .6 .5 12.1 12.3 Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% #Source: Robbth,W. David, Consumer Instalment Loans, Ohio State University, 1955, p. 49. *Source: Based on a 1962 study by the National Consumer Finance Association. See: National Consumer Finance Association, Finance Facts YearbookL41965, Washington, D.C., p. 58. The experience of the Albany and Charleston sample is quite similar to national patterns. Approximately 31% of the Albany loans were unsecured while 30.2% of the Charleston l . . . . . National Consumer Finance Assoc1ation, Finance Facts Yearbook, 1965, p. 58. 2 Robbins, Op.cit., p. 49. 152 borrowers offer no tangible security. There is a slightly higher number of loans secured by household goods in Charles- ton, but the combined total of motor vehicle and household good loans is similar in both cities. It is quite interesting to note the similarity of: l) the eXperienceS N.m .muh N.m Acmwsv coaummsooo ca .muw am + saw xmm macromamu x Xm I .amm goo ocaocmu x .mu> m I .muw 0H .mH% n AcmmEv mocmcfimmu CH mnmww RH I Roe sea ooomumomm one omouo>ao x RH I Raw Ram muwzouuon mama X o .muh mm .mum m¢ AcmmEv mod Hm” + seem moem lemmas meooaa manages mEmumMm muoum ca Umcsaocfl muouomw ufltmuo RH I mom xflm omuooomes x xe + xme x5e assooom xemn :0w3.x Xe I .xmm xmm moan ouflr3.uo x Km + _th Row mumBOHuon ucmmwum.x mam + omw new lemmas .muesm saruaoz memo + Hmoam oomaw lemmas name mo uaooea oaw I sum smm lemmas emoq to mono mEmume mswuoom CH UmUDHUcH uoc muouomm UHUwHU mucflom v I mUCHom who mucflom mos AcmmEV muoom .00 mocmcflm macaom HHI mucfiom ooma musflom HHNH Acmmsv whoom Sufism mumBOHuon coummHumzo mo cowmwaumsv mcmna< =mmwcflxwflu: HmcoHUHctm uwz .¢>.3 .zoemmumamo oz< .w.z .wzmmqm 2H mmmzommom mom mmmoom eHnmmo ozm mezmzmqm MmHm mo ZOmHmmmzoo 0N.¢ mam¢9 CHAPTER V EVALUATION OF THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Is the Hypothesis Confirmed? The basic issue this study attempts to clarify is whether or not there is a positive relationship between the rates charged by consumer finance companies and the risk accepted into their loan portfolios. The approach to re- solving this issue was three fold: l) a study of management policy as reported by company representatives, 2) a statistical study of the correlation between chargeoff rates, turndown rates, and gross yields, and 3) a detailed comparison of borrower and rejected loan applicant characteristics in a state where lenders charge a relatively high rate and in a state where the rate is lower. The conclusions from the three studies are: there is a positive relationship between risk acceptance and rate levels, but further detailed study of borrower characteristics must be done before this relationship can be accurately measured. A study showing a moderate rela- tionship between chargeoff rate and gross yield was more con- clusive than a study comparing personal applicant characteristics 161 162 in Albany, New York and Charleston, West Virginia. The dis- similarity of financial characteristics, however, supports the validity of the hypothesis. Since the evidence is predicated on risk measurement assumptions, the conclusions are only as reliable as the validity of these assumptions. This chapter presents the conclusions of the study and examines their validity in terms of the assumptions and risk measurements used to evaluate the data. Tests of the Hypothesis Managerial Policy Managerial policies toward risk acceptance flexibility and rate differentials are somewhat inconsistent. Six of the seven major finance company representatives interviewed assert there is no change in credit availability because of rate differentials. The implication is clear that risk standards are determined on an average cost basis where profits from larger loans compensate for the lossess on smaller loans and where the favorable experiences from the "good" loans compen- sate for the losses on the "bad" loans.1 There is no conscious effort for management to determine output on the basis of marginal cost and marginal revenue analysis. Rather, output The term "losses" is nebulous, however, since these amounts depend on the method of cost allocation and the definition of direct and fixed costs. 163 is determined on the basis Of acceptable average returns and costs. Middle management views the relationship differently, however, since loan supervisors adjust risk by altering acceptable chargeoff rates. Rate differentials influence credit standard criteria when loan supervisors evaluate branch manager loan judgment on both active and rejected accounts. Since the supervisor's Opinion Of branch manager judgment influences loan patterns, he informally sets credit standards. Most supervisors admit their loan judgment is somewhat flex- ible, depending on whether or not they can "afford" to adjust standards. It is difficult to say which view is more correct, tOp management's or middle management's, but loan supervisors are closer to the actual Operation. There probably is a tendency to adapt credit standards to the income produced by finance charges. While tOp managers assert a rigid credit standard policy the competition of other financial institutions may force them to consciously or unconsciously alter their standards in order to effectively compete within their area. Management intentions may not vary, but local competition may affect the implementation Of credit standard policies. Test I The statistical results from associating gross yield 164 levels with chargeoff rates confirmsthe hypothesis tolerably ‘well. A partial correlation analysis shows a moderate but significant relationship between the variables for all three firms. A summary of the results Of correlating chargeoff rates with gross yield is shown in Table 5.1. TABLE 5.1 SIMPLE AND PARTIAL CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS (r) OF CHARGEOFF RATE AND GROSS YIELD, FOR THREE FINANCE COMPANIES m _1 w Firm X Firm Y Firm Z Simple (r) .38 .28 .41 Partial (r) .26 .31 .28 The relationship Of turndown rates and gross yield is not conclusive and the coefficients Of correlation for all three firms clearly are not significant. Rejection rates appear to be unreliable and inaccurate proxies for risk acceptance. A summary Of the results of correlating turn- down rates and gross yield is shown in Table 5.2. Validity of Test I as a Measure of Risk Acceptance and Rate Relationship To rely on chargeoff rates as a measure Of risk acceptance and gross yield as a measure of finance charge level may be 165 TABLE 5.2 SIMPLE AND PARTIAL CORRELATION COEFFICIENTS (r) OF TURNDOWN RATE AND GROSS YIELD, FOR THREE FINANCE COMPANIES m Firm X Firm Y Simple (r) -.03 -.05 Partial (r) -.12 —.10 assuming too much, however. While chargeoff rate is one mea- sure Of risk assumption cost, it is inextricably associated ‘with other costs. A firm can substitute collection efforts and investigation expenses to replace chargeoff expenses and since these three expenses are interdependent, only their total amount provides an accurate indication Of lender risk assumption costs. The analysis of Test I does not consider collection and investigation costs because it is very difficult to allocate employee salaries and wages according to the various functions performed. Therefore, chargeoff rates are used as a proxy for risk acceptance. It is an inexact measure, to be sure, but it does provide a rough measure Of borrower risk. Gross yield percentages do not portray the whole story on rates since revenue from insurance premiums is an additional source of income not included in the gross yield amount. By "suggesting" that borrowers purchase life, accident, and health 166 insurance policies to protect the borrower in the event Of tragedy, finance companies secure additional revenue. The amount of earnings from this source varies due to the various regulations on insurance charges. Therefore, gross yield presents a rather inaccurate portrayal of company earnings, although it does provide an adequate "rough" measure. Test II The third measure Of risk and rate relationship is a detailed comparison of borrower and rejected characteristics in a low rate state with those in a high rate state. A com- parison of applicants from three major finance companies in Charleston, West Virginia where the rate is relatively high with those from the same firms in Albany, New York where the rate is relatively low indicates a small difference in their personal characteristics. The close similarity of the "scores“ of applicants in each city is strong evidence of a constant risk-rate relationship—-contrary to the hypothesis assertion. Table 5.3 illustrates the comparison Of applicant character- istics in each city. A more detailed analysis shows a striking similarity between most applicant characteristics except for 1) residence stability, 2) monthly income, 3) in- stalment debt, and 4) monthly payments. There is greater applicant resident stability in Charleston, indicating less risk, but smaller applicant income and greater debt, indicating 167 TABLE 5.3 SUMMARY OF CHARACTERISTICS OF BORROWERS AND REJECTED LoAN APPLICANTS IN ALBANY AND CHARLESTON, 1964—1965, by MEAN AVERAGE Borrower Rejected Accounts Accounts Albany Charleston Albany Charleston Borrower Characteristics Personal Characteristics Age - Yrs. 42.2 42.6 33.5 32.6 NO. in Family 3.2 3.2 2.7 2.9 Yrs. in Res. 7.0 9.9 4.8 7.4 Yrs. in Occup. 9.2 9.2 3.5 3.1 Financial Characteristics Monthly Income $468 $448 $357 $306 Monthly Payment $77 $96 $43 $46 Instalment Debt $1306 $1682 $782 $816 Amount of Loan $587 $576 $389 $350 Payment on Loan $31 $29 -— —- Debt to Annual Income Ratio by Credit Rating Tests .23 .31 .18 .22 Scores Smith System Score 1200 1211 1591 1599 Consumer Finance Com— pany System Score 773 777 526 613 A lower score on the Smith test indicates better credit. A.higher score on the Consumer Finance Company test indi- cates better credit. 168 more risk. In order to assess a final risk amount, the finan- cial differences must be compared to the residential chara- teristics. On balance, lenders in Charleston appear to accept slightly more risk as the added financial burdens of applicants appear to outweigh their tendency toward increased home ownership and residential stability. Validity Of Test II as a Measure of Risk Acceptance and Rate Relationship A serious limitation to a comparison Of this type is the “haterggeneityoflegal regulations in each state. While pains- taking effort was made to select economically similar cities, there are interstate differences in the allowable collection methods lenders are permitted to use. Since it is easier to assign borrower wages in New York than in west Virginia col- lection costs are apt to be lower in New York, allowing firms to accept more risk. State regulations toward debtor and creditor remedies vary and must also be considered when assessing credit standards. Another legal regulation affecting loan Operations is the status Of "convenience and advantage" laws in each state. Most states have laws requiring new licensees to show "con- venience and advantage," but these laws are enforced with 2For a succinct summary of the advantages and disadvant— ages Of convenience and advantage laws, see Neifeld, M.R., Neifeld's Manual on Consumer Credit, Mack Publishing Co., Easton, Penn., 1961, pp. 95-98. {H : ‘. "hug-‘12:- _‘u- '91.- - an. a 169 varying degrees of severity. In New York, for example, the law is more strictly enforced than West Virginia. While casual Observation can be misleading, one has only to walk on the main streets of Charleston to notice the greater num- ber of loan Offices there than in Albany. Of course, this could also be a reflection Of their rate level differences. The relative merits and drawbacks Of convenience and advant- age laws are too numerous to mention here, but where a strict interpretation Of the law exists, branch Offices have greater Opportunities to achieve economies of scale. A recent study shows the Optimum number of accounts in a branch Office to be between 2,000 and 2,500.3 In states where "C & A" laws are strict, firms can afford to accept greater losses and still maintain a "fair" rate Of return since larger sized 3Athorough analysis Of loan size and unit cost rela- tzionships shows a decreasing cost relationship between branch <>ffice size and unit costs. Other studies verify these Jresults, but there are dissenting views which argue that loan C>ffices have constant costs. Of course, a large part of this .Elroblem reverts to a definition Of "costs". The nature Of lfiinance company costs is not within the purview Of this study 1But the following sources discuss the problem in detail. Comiskey, Eugene E., "A Study Of Loan Cost Behavior in <2CDnsumer Finance Companies," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, 1“’1—‘ii.chigan State University, 1965. Farwell, Loring C., "Cost and Output Relationships of c-‘-<>nsumer Instalment Credit Agencies, Based on Reports of :[Ildiana Licensees," unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, North- w’Gastern University, 1955. Miller, Upton, "The Importance of Direct Costs in the (31?anting Of Consumer Instalment Credit," unpublished Ph.D. dlssertation, Northwestern University, 1948. Anal-h." 4....I. v -g:.. 5!. mum-c“ and PF‘ ‘ l 7 170 branch offices tend to have lower unit costs. The Offices where the sample data were secured are very similar in size and average between 1,000 and 2,000 accounts per Office, although one Office in Charleston is somewhat smaller. All are considered mature downtown offices. Therefore, economies or diseconomies of scale shouldn't affect the risk acceptance level differences in the sample, although they may affect Operations elsewhere. 1 I Because of the more liberal convenience and advantage E I laws in West Virginia there is a greater tendency for consumer 1 finance companies to compete with each other, although the amount Of increased competition because Of these laws is uncertain. The greater number of Offices in Charleston makes it somewhat tenuous to assert that the supply market Of con- sumer credit is similar in both areas. Competitive differences are also affected by other factors. For instance, the greater concentration of employees in the chemical industry in Charleston suggests company or labor union credit COOperatives more actively compete with consumer finance companies and affect the type Of applicants they are likely to attract. On the other hand, this tendency is balanced by the relatively greater number Of persons employed by the State Of New York in Albany which also has credit unions. Since this dissertation doesn't include a study Of market structure, 171 the strength and effect Of these differences is not measured. However, loan market structure is influential in determining loan quality and delinquency losses. The amount of commercial bank branch banking and its affect on competition with consumer finance companies is also influential in ascertaining the nature of applicants securing credit at finance companies. Inter—industry competition is important but it was not explicitly considered in the study. E There is no doubt, however, that in general commercial banks % are now competing more aggressively for consumer credit accounts. “a.” _—‘-. ".9. I It must also be remembered that the data from Test II represents acceptance patterns from only three finance com- panies, all large. It is quite conceivable "independent" finance companies have a different set Of credit standards. Major finance companies may tend to be more inflexible and may not adapt to local loan markets as readily as the smaller state and local Operations. It would be very useful to com— pare borrower loan quality from the independent finance com- panies with that from major finance companies. However, there is no presumption the three large companies are not representative of the whole industry. The 1950 data compiled by Robbins shows little difference in loan size for the 4 various types Of firms granting consumer credit. His data Robbins, W. David, Consumer Instalment Loans, Ohio State University, 1955, p. 39. 172 from the Ohio area show "contrary to such belief (that chain organization 'skim the cream' Of the loan market) no striking difference is to be Observed between chain and independent companies in regard to the amount Of money which they lend to borrowers." Of course, other applicant characteristics may differ between firms. Significance of Hypothesis to Intra—Firm Risk Discrimination The hypothesis asserts that output is determined on a marginal cost and revenue basis where risk cost differentials '1'; li'fl" IAIN Air Mm r.‘:~.u.r-.--o' _v u. .v r: -. are matched with the revenue increments. The marginal analy— sis application can be extended even further, however. By varying rates to match the costs of borrowers according to their risk class, firms can more effectively compete with other lending institutions. The most efficient and accurate method Of achieving this is with a credit scoring system whereby those applicants scoring in the lower risk brackets would receive a favorable rate while those scoring in a higher risk bracket would pay a higher rate. Of course, this mechanism is fraught with many administrative diffi- culties and extra costs, but an experimental test seems feasible. One major finance company executive indicates his firm is presently considering this approach. The advantage Of such a system is Obvious_-consumer finance companies would be\better able to compete with 173 commercial banks and other financial institutions who charge lower rates and make larger loans. Applicants falling into the poorer risk classifications would have to "pay their own way" since the expected returns from their risk class must match the expected costs of credit losses, collection costs, etc. The drawbacks are Obvious too--administration costs would be higher, but this does not seem to be an insurmountable problem. Though initial training and installation costs would be higher, the variable costs Of day to day operation would tend to diminish after some experience with the system. ‘Ugbiuvzn mrflc-htour ox» «no» .r -_ Many argue that competition would force firms to grant lower rates to all applicants because those in the lower risk classi- fications would "shOp around" until they secured a more favor- able rate. Is is somewhat true that competition would be keen, but if a competitor accepts a lower scored applicant he also assumes more marginal cost than the revenue warrants unless he has superior insight into the borrower's loan repay- ment tendencies. Otherwise he will lose money on this account. If the competitor is more efficient in securing loan repay- ment, then resources should be allocated to this firm. In the longer run, there would be more competition and vitality in the whole consumer finance industry. Not alone would the borrowing public be better Off because each person would be paying a rate commensurate with his risk, but finance companies 174 would have a much larger market base and could more effectively compete with other institutions. This proposal is dependent on a substantial revision Of state laws dealing with loan size ceilings.5 In order to effectively compete with commercial banks and credit unions, consumer finance companies must be allowed to better serve the public with larger loans. In effect, a broader definition . Uh P.fi§’ .~ P 11!" Q'I ". of the consumer finance industry is needed to include all legal institutions granting consumer credit rather than just Small Loan Licensees. I “”3 Runs “1:51“ «1a- n. a. . Significance of Findings to Public Policy Deductive presumption indicates that Test II should have disclosed a stronger positive relationship between applicant personal characteristics and rate. The differences in annual gross yields between the two states is substantial--about nine percentage points. Why aren't more poorer risk borrowers accepted by lenders in Charleston? There are two probable answers: 1) finance company managers do not use marginal analysis in determining output and, therefore, set credit standards based on national averages Of revenues and costs, 5The need for larger loan ceilings has been proposed by many sources. See Phelps, Clyde W., “Consumer Finance Charges II, Journal of Marketing, July, 1952, pp. 27-32. Kawaja, Michael, "On the Inflexibility of Small Loan Rates and Loan Size Ceilings," Personal Finance Law Quarter- ly Repgrt, Spring, 1965, pp. 57-59. 175 and 2) the acceptance of greater risk in a high rate state would lead to a disprOportionate increase in marginal and average costs. Since loan supervisors tend to adjust risk standards under various rates, there undoubtedly is greater considera- tion Of marginal analysis than tOp managers assert.. It is tors-14"" uncertain to what extent this is true because the mechanism for risk standard adjustment is too informal and inexact. Managers also assert that the acceptance of more lower risk applicants would disprOportionately add to costs not 'mnnms-M us ‘1... .l . 5x”.”A 1 warranted by the marginal revenue. This may be valid, but the evidence of Test II indicates a fairly large overlap between borrower and rejected account scores and it appears that a greater portion of accounts could be included into the loan portfolio. (Charts 4.1, 4.2, 4.3 and Tables 4.4 and 4.5) 1 It is true that some states with higher rates may have, some inherent characteristics causing higher costs. Lower pOpulation density in some states makes investigation and collection costs larger than in areas where population density is high resulting in less physical effort and expense to collect accounts. Population density also affects the scale Of Operation since a firm serving a larger number of accounts will achieve increased economies of scale. Factor 176 prices as wages and rents also vary geographically and affect cost levels. Even so, there is a real question of whether or not higher rates are the result Of higher costs or the cause of them. Finance companies as well as individuals have a tendency to slacken their efficiency when "times are good". When in- come is at a satisfactory level, the additional efforts to "wring out" the last efficient dollar is not worth the addi- tional revenue. Money has definite non-linear utility. The decidedly higher level of net income in West Virginia compared to New York suggests that the higher permissible rate charged haless for risk assumption and passes through to profits without performing its intended function. In 1964, the average net yield after taxes but before interest was 7.15%»for West Virginia Licensees and 5.49%.for New York Licensees. If the yield is adequate in New York, and there is no reason to think otherwise, then the amount over the adequate rate could be considered excess. Given the com- plexities of determining net yield after considering fixed and variable costs, interest, and taxes, the higher gross yield in west Virginia results in firms earning higher than adequate yields, if New York Licensees earnings are used as an example of adequate yield. (An investigation Of the num— ber of new loan Offices in low rate states would provide some 177 indication of whether finance companies consider their present rate adequate.) A useful type of analysis would be a correlation of state gross yield and net yield experiences to indicate whether those allowing higher finance charges also have lenders with higher net earnings. If lenders earn more in states allowing higher rates, there is a real question whether the higher rates are justified. A recent study shows finance companies charging higher rates with lower net yields, but the data is not categorized by state. _,.,—__._-_- .Am _u -x‘A‘ut-h.. W a ~ n I. . , v v a . . .. . ~ ~ ._ A . n .. If further research indicates that small loan companies‘ do not substantially increase risk assumption in return for being allowed to charge higher rates, than there is real reason for doubting the validity of allowing higher finance charges, such as in West Virginia. The data from Test II are somewhat conclusive in showing risk differentials, but the west Virginia chargeoff rate is only slightly higher than the rate in New York. It is also uncertain whether or not the apparent larger borrowing power of Charleston borrowers is large enough to justify the higher rates. If the pattern disclosed in two states are representative Of the borrowing public, then what is the rationale for permitting a rate higher 6Smith, Paul F., Consumer Credit Costs, 1949-1959, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1964, p. 25. 178 than the average 20.33%7 in New York if chargeoff rates and risk acceptance standards do not rise accordingly? If the finance rate is acceptable in New York and a similar type of applicant is served in West Virginia where the average rate is approximately 29%,8 then what are their reasons for allow- ing this higher rate. Additional collection and investigation expense may account for some of the differences, but it is debateable whether or not it provides an adequate explanation. - The traditional argument for higher rate ceilings rests on the assumption that higher cost levels in a particular 'Wr.—n~-nu ‘1‘. . 1min . I 1 ' . A' state make higher finance charges imperative if sufficient capital is to be Obtained. The existence of cost differences is somewhat valid since a recent study shows that firms charging higher rates generally sustain higher overall costs in almost all cost classifications and accounts.9 General Summary The crucial policy question this study attempts to answer is whether or not states are justified in permitting Small Loan Licensees to charge borrowers higher finance charges. The evidence suggests that lenders better serve the community 7Annual Report of the Superintendent Of Banks, State of New York, 1964, p. 97. 8Consolidated Report of the Small Loan Licensees Of west Virginia, 1964, p. 5. 9 Smith, Op.cit., p. 25. 179 and extend more credit to borrowers when allowed to charge higher rates, but the evidence is too incomplete to draw broad generalizations. Before this issue can be fully answered there must be further research of borrower characteristics in many states and from many finance companies. In addition, the role Of other influences on risk acceptance--loan size ceilings, convenience and advantage laws, and allowable 1 collection practices--must all be studied. If evidence 1 from additional research substantiates and confirms the im- plication of the positive risk and rate relationship derived from Tests I and II, then higher rate ceilings are justified. Whether or not it is desirable for borrowers to be eli- gible for more credit is not a matter Of economic science, but a social value judgment. APPENDICES 180 DOLLAR CHARGES ON DIFFERENT SIZE LOANS REPAID ACCORDING TO CONTRACT (12 MOS.) AT LAWFUL MAXIMUM RATES OF CHARGE UNDER 44 SMALL LOAN LAWS ARRANGED BY LOAN SIZE CEILING 181 APPENDIX A Rate Loan Size 4§100 $300 $500 $1000 $1500 CANADA 2-l-%%(300—1000) $13.46 $40.44 $60.76 $98.72 $126.60 UNITED STATES $1500 Loan Ceiling or Over California 2%-2-5/6%(200-500) $16.88 $49.32 $77.80 $123.08 $156.24 Colorado 3—15-l%(300-500) 20.48 61.56 92.08 139.40 177.12 Kansas 3—5/6%(300) 20.48 61.56 87.64 125.36 156.24 Maine 3-2%-1%%(150-300) 20.60 58.44 86.32 141.56 193.44 Massachusetts 2fi-2-1 3/4-3/4%(200-600-1000) 16.88 49.32 77.80 142.76 189.00 Missouri 2.218-2/3%(500) 14.96 44.88 74.92 119.24 148.20 Nebraska 28—2—15-1%(300-500—1000) 16.88 50.88 81.40 141.08 187.08 Nevada Add-on: 9-8%(1000) + fee 21.00 57.00 81.00 126.00 166.00 New Hampshire Add-on: 16-12%(600) 16.00 48.00 80.00 144.00 204.00 Ohio Add-on: 16-9-7%(500-1000) 16.00 48.00 80.00 125.00 160.00 Oregon 3-2—1%(300—500) 20.60 61.68 95.68 147.68 186.84 South Dakota 3-3/4%(300) 20.84 62.52 88.36 124.16 152.88 Texas Add-on: 19-16-13-11-9-7%(100-200- 300-500-1000) 19.00 48.00 70.00 115.00 150.00 $1000 Loan Ceiling $100 A§3OO $500 $1000 Alaska 4—2%-2%(300-600) 28.28 84.72 129.76 215.48 Arizona 3-2-1%(300-600) 20.48 61.56 95.56 154.16 Connecticut Add-on: l7-9%(300) 17.00 51.00 69.00 114.00 Idaho 3—2-1%(300—500) 20.48 61.56 95.56 147.68 Indiana 3-2-1%%(150-300) 20.84 56.16 81.52 135.80 Michigan 25-1%%(300) 17.24 51.72 77.44 125.60 Montana Add-on: 20-16-12%(300-500) 20.00 60.00 92.00 152.00 New Mexico 3-25-l%(150-300) 20.48 58.44 82.84 123.68 North Dakota 28-2—1 3/4-18%(250-500-750) 16.88 50.52 79.72 142.16 Washington 3-13-l%(300-500) 20.48 61.56 92.08 139.40 Wyoming 3%—28-l%(150—300) 24.20 66.00 91.24 132.44 $800 Loan Ceiling $100 $300 $500 $800 Illinois 3-2-1%(150-300) 20.48 55.32 77.08 101.44 Kentucky Add-on: 20-15-11%(150-600) 20.00 52.44 82.48 119.44 New York 2%-2-3/4%(100-300) 16.88 45.72 64.72 84.40 West Virginia Add-on: l9—16—12%(200—600) 19.00 54.00 86.00 126.00 $600 Loan Ceiling §100 $300 §500 ,_§600 Florida 3-2%(300) 20.84 62.52 97.00 112.20 Minnesota 2 3/4-1%%(300) 18.68 56.28 85.00 97.08 North Carolina Add-on: 20—18—15-6%(100-200-300) 20.00 53.00 65.00 71.00 Pennsylvania 3-2-l%(150-300) 20.60 55.32 77.08 85.80 Utah 3-l%(300) 20.84 62.52 90.04 99.96 Vermont 2%-2%—1%(125-300) 17.24 49.56 72.16 81.00 Virginia 2%-1%%(300) 17.24 51.72 79.12 90.96 $500 Loan Ccilipg $100 $300 $500 Iowa 3-2—1%%(150-300) 20.84 56.16 81.52 New Jersey 2%—%%(300) 17.00 51.00 71.44 $300 Loan Ceilipg $100 $300 Alabama 3-2%(200) 20.48 58.44 Hawaii 33-2%%(100) 24.56 62.64 Louisiana 3%-2%%(150) 24.56 66.96 Maryland 3% 20.60 61.68 Rhode Island 3% 20.84 62.52 Wisconsin 2%-2-1(100-200) 17.00 42.84 Source: A Major Consumer Finance Company. 182 APPENDIX B CONSUMER FINANCE COMPANIES SUPPLYING INFORMATION USED IN STUDY American Investment Company of Illinois Beneficial Finance Company C. I. T. Financial Corporation General Finance Corporation Household Finance Corporation Liberty Loan Corporation Seaboard Finance Company 183 APPENDIX C SIMPLE AND PARTIAL CORRELATION COEFFICIENT FORMULAS Simple Correlation Coefficient:* (23C 9 V 22.2 (2:) *5 3:11-0:02 Partial Correlation Coefficient:# r12.3 = r12 ’ r13 r23 _ 2 _ 2 1Vr1 r13 1 r23 For 3 variables held constant: r12.345 = r12.34 - r15.34 r25.34 I 2 2 Wi-r 15.34)V(1-r 25.34)