/:» 4/1, /1/& 7’ / 4/7 / {’7 ,3 c 5’ RETURNING MATERIALS: /:3 49¢? MSU P1ace in book drop to ‘ remove this checkout from your record. FINES will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. LIBRARIES “_ i grew. DEanulQ. , r.‘ ;. hLNEW ’ 1 1. PESTICIDES AND POLICY: RISK-BENEFIT ANALYSIS AT THE ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY BY Patty Teresa Skelding A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE Department of Agricultural Economics 1984 J, '\ V..- b ' . t \‘ ‘~ ABSTRACT PESTICIDES AND POLICY: RISK BENEFIT ANALYSIS AT THE ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY BY Patty Teresa Skelding There has been much criticism of the 0.8. Environmental Protection Agency's regulation of pesticides, but very little empirical work to describe that process. In this research, the quality of EPA's information on risks and benefits of pesticide use is quantified for eight case-study pesticides, using EPA documents. Goodman and Kruskal's coefficient of ordinal association measures correlations between those data and five explanatory variables depicting interest group incentives to influence the regulatory pro- cess. The five explanatory variables are: value of pesti- cide use to manufacturers, percent of crop treated, per acre user losses, total user losses, agiégigg”S§:§BEWEESEEEIE§> These variables are also quantified from EPA documents. T37 general, risk information was poorer than benefits informa- tion, interest groups do not influence risk information, manufacturers and users influence benefits information, the pesticide's relative risk does not influence benefit infor- mation, and pesticide manufacturers and users impact EPA decisions. I/ ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank several people who made the com- pletion of this arduous project possible. My husband Mark stayed by my side during the setbacks as well as the vic- tories, and he suffered more than any spouse should. My parents and several close friends, including Diane Smith and Charles and Katy Abdalla, gave me the extra push I needed to keep going. My Major Professor and Thesis Advisor, Dr. Eileen van Ravenswaay, was a constant source of creativity, knowledge, incentive and support. I am intellectually indebted to her, and I also owe her a great deal for her patience. The other members of my thesis committee, Dr. Warren Samuels and Dr. Lawrence Libby, also contributed a great deal to the final product of this research. I also deeply appreciate the generous financial support for this project from the Michigan State University Agricul- tural Experiment Station and the 0.5. Department of Agricul- ture Economic Research Service. Above all, I thank the people of Community Church of Owosso and I thank God. -11- TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES O...00....OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOCOOOOOOOOO Vi LIST OF FIGURES .COCOOOCOOOCOOOOOOOO0..0.0...OOOIOOOOOOOIOOOOOOO XVi CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION OVERVIEW .................................................... 1 THE RESEARCH PROBLEM ........................................ 3 THE RESEARCH SETTING: EPA REGULATION OF PESTICIDES .......... 10 ORGANIZATION OF THE THESIS .................................. 20 CHAPTER 2: THEORIES OF THE REGULATORY PROCESS: A REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE INTRODUCTION ................................................ 22 THE NATURE OF REGULATION .................................... 22 THEORIES OF REGULATORY DECISION MAKING ...................... 29 Theories With Agency-Wide Objective Functions .......... 29 Agency survival ................................... 30 Budget-maximizing or size-maximizing agencies ..... 39 Summary -- theories with agency-wide objective functions ........................................ 43 Theories Assuming Different Goals Within an Agency ..... 44 coalitions Of regulators 0......OOOCOOIOOOOOOOOOOOO 45 Unique objective functions for individual regulators ....................................... 47 THE USE OF INFORMATION IN REGULATORY DECISION MAKING ........ 52 Is More Information Better? ............................ 52 Characteristics of Information Search .................. 53 The Use of Information ................................. 57 'Information leads to rational decisions ........... 57 Information is used by conflicting interests to influence decision makers ..................... 57 Information legitimizes decisions ................. 58 Information clarifies issues and potential solutions ........................................ 60 Multiple uses of information ...................... 61 Summary: The Nature and Use of Information in Regulatory Decision Making ............................ 62 EPA'S REGULATION OF PESTICIDES: DETERMINANTS OF DECISION MAKING AND USES OF INFORMATION .................... 63 HAPTER 3: CONCEPTUALIZING THE IMPACTS OF PESTICIDE USE INTRODUCTION ................................................ 66 OVERVIEW OF EPA'S ANALYSIS OF PESTICIDES .................... 66 PROBLEMS IN CONCEPTUALIZING RISKS AND BENEFITS .............. 68 -iii- The Amount of Information and Difficulties in TraCAng Impacts OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOVOOOOOOO Value Judgments in Risk-Benefit Analysis ............... CONCEPTUALIZING THE IMPACTS OF PESTICIDE USE ................ . R18k Measurement OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO'OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO TOXiC1ty OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO‘OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO EnVironmental fate O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O exposure OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO The risk analysis ................................. The measurement 0: Benefits O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Theoretical discussion of the net benefits OE pestiCide use O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Real impaCts O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Distribution of impacts ........................... PROBLEMS IN MEASURING IMPACTS ............................... CHAPTER 4:.METHODOLOGY - INTRODUCTION OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 91 CHOICE OF DATA BASE OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 91 MEASURING EXPLANATORY VARIABLES ............................. 94 wniCh variableS? OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 94 How "eaaured? OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 98 Value of pesticide use to manufacturers ........... 99 Value of pesticide use to producers ............... 100 Percentage of producers affected .................. 104 Losses to risk-bearers ............................ 105 Problems in measuring explanatory variables ....... 108 MEASURING DEPENDENT VARIABLES OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 109 mien measured? OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 109 80" measured? OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 113 Problems in Measuring Dependent Variables .............. 122 Specific comments on risk coding .................. 122 General comments on risk coding ................... 122 . General comments on benefits coding ............... 126 MANIPULATING DATA FOR COMPARISON BETWEEN PESTICIDES ......... 127 MEASURING CORRELATION BETWEEN DEPENDENT AND EXPLANATORY VARIABLES OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 129 SUMMARY OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO I133 CHAPTER 5: RESULTS: QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON RISK OF PESTICIDE USE ‘ INTRODUCTION OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 137- OVBRVIEW OF EPA'S RISK ASSESSMENT PROCESS eeeeeeeeeeeeeeeeee'e 137 QUALITY OF EPA'S RISK INFORMATION OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO‘OOOO 1‘2 CORRELATION BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND . QUALITY OF RISK INFORMATION VARIABLES ...................... 146 Explanation of Tables .................................. 146 Findings for Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers ... 150 Findings for Percent of Crop Treated .................... 158 Findings for Annual Per Acre User Losses ............... 160 Findings for Annual Total User Losses .................. 161 Findings for EPA' s Risk Ranking ........................ 163 —v- Summary: Correlation Between Explanatory Variables and Quality of Information on Risk .................... CHAPTER 6: RESULTS: QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON BENEFITS OF PESTICIDE USE ...................................... GENERAL OBSERVATIONS ON EPA'S BENEFITS ANALYSIS ............. THE QUALITY OF EPA'S BENEFITS INFORMATION ................... CORRELATION BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND THE QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON BENEFITS ..................... Findings for Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers ... Findings for Percent of Crop Treated ................... Findings for Annual Per Acre User Losses ............... Findings for Annual Total User Losses .................. Findings for EPA's Risk Ranking ........................ Findings for All of the Explanatory Variables and EPA's Decisions on Pesticide Registration ......... Summary: Correlation Between Explanatory Variables and Quality of Information on Benefits ................ CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSIONS OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH ........................................ SUMMARY OF RESULTS .......................................... ANALYSIS OF RESULTS ......................................... Value Judgments in Pesticide Regulation ................ Correlation Between Variables .......................... EPA: Vote-Maximizer or Budget-Maximizer? ............... Predicted results for vote-maximizing agency ...... Predicted results for budget-maximizing agency .... Summary: EPA Incentives and Recommendations to Achieve Change ........................................ THE ROLE OF INFORMATION: IMPLICATIONS FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS ............................................ IMPLICATIONS OF FINDINGS FOR PROPOSED REGULATORY REFORMS .... The Bush Task Force Reforms ............................ National Academy of Sciences Recommendations ........... DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH .............................. APPENDICES APPENDIX A: RANKING OF PESTICIDE USES ACCORDING TO FOUR EXPLANATORY VARIABLES .............................. APPENDIX B: CORRELATIONS BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND QUALITY OF INFORMATION ....................... BIBLIOGRAPHY ......OOOOOOOOO......OCOOOOOOOOOO.........OOOOOOOOOO 165 167 167 170 174 177 180 182 184 187 189 191 194 195 197 197 198 201 201 202 204 206 208 208 212 215 217 225 294 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 4.1 4.2 4.14 4.15 LIST OF TAB; ES Value to Manufacturers of Uses of DBCP. . Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancel- lation for DBCP (Annual)O OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Annual Per Acre and Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation for DBCP. ... Percentage of Acres Treated with DBCP (Per Crop Cycle). Measuring Relative Risk for Amitraz. .... EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking: Criteria Used to Determine Risk and Score for Each PestiCideO OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.000000000000 Typical Risk Variables for Which Quality of Information was Measured. ............ Benefits Variables for Which Quality of Information was Measured. ............... Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: TOXiCitYe .....OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Exposure. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa~ tion: Dermal and Inhalation Exposure. .. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Risk Assessment. ................. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Risk of Alternative Pest Control. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Acute Toxicity to Wildlife. ..... Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Significant Decreases in Nontarget Populations. .....O...’ 100 102 103 105 106 107 111 112 115 115 116 116 116 117 118 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 4.16 4.17 4.20 4.21 5.3 5.4 5.5 -vii- Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Fatality to Endangered Species. .. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- All Changes in Pest Control Costs and Changes in Value of Production Data Except Price. tion: Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- tion: Price. OOOOOOOOOO........OOOOOOOCOOOOOOOOOO. Measurement Scale for Quality of Informa- Per Acre Change in Pest Control tion: Costs, Costs, duction, duction, Costs, GOOdSI Nonusers, facturers), economic Impacts, Total Change in Pest Control Per Acre Change in Value of Pro- Change Impacts Distribution of Marketers, Geographic on in Social Impacts, Other Producers of Impacts Consumers, Impacts, Total Change in Value of Pro- Production Other (Users, Manu~ Macro- Degree of Compliance, Costs of Restrictions. .. Measurement Scale for EPA Decision. Specific Problems in Measuring Dependent Risk Variables. Calculation Chlorobenzilate: Calculation EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Consumer Risk of Oncogenicity. Quality of Risk Information. of Gamma Coefficient for Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers and Consumer Risk of Oncogenicity. of Gamma Coefficient for Number of Uses Measured for Each Pesti- cide According to Explanatory Variables. Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Risk Data and Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturer. Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Risk Data and Percent of Crop Tested. Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Risk Data and Annual Per Acre User LOSSOS. ......OCOOOOOOOOOOO000......OOOOOO 119 120 120 121 121 123 134 135 144 151 152 153 -viii- Table 5 .6 Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Risk Data and Annual Total User Losses. ......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 155 Table 5.7 Summary of Correlations Between EPA's Risk Rankimg and the Average Quality of Risk Information. I.........OIOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0...... 164 Table 6.1 Summary of Quality of Benefits Informa- tion. ......OIOOOOO.........OOOOOOOOOOOOI0.00...... 172 Table 6.2 Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Benefits Data and Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturer. .............................. 178 Table 6.3 Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Benefits Data and Percent of Crop Treated. ......OOOO........OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0...... 181 Table 6.4 Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Benefits Data and Annual Per Acre User Losses. OOOOOOOOOOOOO0.000000000000000000000000000. 183 Table 6.5 Summary of Correlations Between Quality of Benefits Data and Annual Total User Losses. ......OOOOOOO0.0000IOOOOOOOOIOOOOOOCOOOOOO. 185 Table 6.6 Summary of Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and the Average Quality of Benefits Information. .................. 188 Table 6. 7 Summary of Correlations Between EPA Pesticide Registration Decisions and Four Explanatory variables. .OOOOOOOOOOOOO OOOOOOO O OOOOOO 190 Table 7.1 Changes in Pesticide Regulation Since President Reagan's Inauguration. .................. 213 Table A1. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Value of Pesticide.................... 217 Table A2. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation. ...................... 219 Table A3. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation. ...................... 221 Table A4. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Percent of Crop Treated. ............. 223 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table .Table Table Table El. 82. B3. B4. 85. 86. B7. 88. B9. 810. 311. ...-ix... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Consumer Risk, as Measured by Gamma. ..................................0...... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Ground Applicator Risk, as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Mixer and Loader Risk. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Pilot Risk, as Measured by Gamma. ........................................0... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Drift. as Measured by Gamma. ...................... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Farmworker Risk, as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Spills, as Measured by Gamma. ..................... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Risk to Aerial Ground Crews. as Measured by Gamma. ...................... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Animal Risk, as Measured by Gamma. .....................................0... Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Consumer Risk, as Measured by Gamma. .............. Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Ground Applicator Risk, as Measured by “mma. ........................................0... 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 812. 813. 814. 815. 816. 817. 818. 819. 820. 821. 822. -x- Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Mixer and Loader Risk. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Pilot Risk Infor- mation. as Measured by Gamma. ..................... Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Drift, as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Farmworker Risk Information, as Measured by Gamma. ................ Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Persons Exposed to Spills, as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Aerial Ground Crew Risk, as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Animal Risk] as measured by Gamma. 0000000000000... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Consumers. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Ground Applicator Risk, as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Mixers and Load- ers, as Measured by Gamma. ........................ Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Pilot Risk, as Measured by Gamma o 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 823. 824. 825. 826. 827. 828. 829. 830. 831. 832. 833. Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Drift. as Measured by Gamma. ...................... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Farmworkers. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Spills. as Measured by Gamma. ..................... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Aerial Ground Crews. as Measured by Gamma. ...................... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Animal Risk. as Measured by Gamma. ...00............OOCOOCOOOOOOCCO0.00....O Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Consumers. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Ground Applica- tors. as Measured by Gamma. ....................... Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Mixers and Loaders. as Measured by Gamma. .................... Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Pilots. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Drift. as Measured by Gamma. ...................... Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Parmworkers. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 834. 835. 836. 837. 838. 839. 840. 841. 842. 843. 844. Correlations Between -xii- Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Spills. as Measured by Gamma. ..................... Correlations Information Crews. Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of on Between Annual Total Risk as Measured by Gamma. ......OOOOOOOOOOOOO... to Aerial Ground User Losses from Cancellation and Quality of Information on Animal Risk. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Consumer Risk. as Measured by Gamma. .............. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Pilot Risk. as Measured by Gamma. ................. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Drift. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Farmworker Risk. as Measured by Gamma. ............ Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Aerial Ground Crew Risk. Gamma. as Measured by Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Risk to Persons Exposed to Accidents and Spills. as Measured by Gamma. ..................... Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Ground Mixer and Loader Risk. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Pesticide Toxicity. as Measured by Gamma. ......... 258 259 260 261 261 262 262 263 263 264 264 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 845. 846. 847. 848. 849. 850. 851. 852. 853. 854. —xiii- Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Changes in Pest Control Costs from Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Changes in Value of Pro- duction from Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Other Socio-Economic Impacts. as Measured by Gamma. .................... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Distribution of Impacts of Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ......OOOOOOOOOO0.0......OOOOOOOOOO000...... Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Quality of Information on Compliance with Proposed Restrictions. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Value of Pesticide Uses to Manufacturers and Pesticide Reg- istration Decisions. as Measured by Gamma. 0.0.0.000.........OOOOOOCUOOOOOOOO0.0.000... Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Changes in Pest Control Costs from Pesti- cide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Changes in Value of Production from Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. O.....O0.000000000000000.........OOOOOOOOOOC Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Other Socio-Economic Impacts. as Measured by Gamma. O......OOOOOC......OOOOCOO00.00.......... Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Distribution of Impacts of Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 273 274 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 855. 856. 857. 858. 859. 860. 861. 862. 863. 864. -xiv— Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Quality of Information on Estimated Compliance with Proposed Restrictions, as HeaSUIEd by Gamma0 000000000000000 Correlations Between Percent of Crop Treated and Pesticide Registration Decisions. as Measured by Gamma. Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses and Quality of Information on Changes in Pest Control Costs from Pesti- cide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. .......... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses and Quality of Information on Changes in Value of Production from Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ................0........................... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information for Other Socio- Economic Impacts. as Measured by Gamma. ........... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Distribution of Impacts of Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Compliance with Proposed Restrictions. as Measured by Gamma. ......O..................................... Correlations Between Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Pesticide Registration Decisions. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Changes in Pest Control Costs from Pesticide Cancella- tion. as Measured by Gamma. ....................... Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Changes in Value of Production from Pesticide Can- cellation. as Measured by Gamma. 275 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 283 284 Table 865. Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Other Socio- Economic Impacts of Pesticide Cancella- tion. as Measured by Gamma. ....................... 285 Table B66. Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Distribution of Impacts from Pesticide Cancellation. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ 286 Table B67. Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Compliance with Proposed Restrictions. as Measured by Gamma. O......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOC......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 287 Table 868. Correlations Between Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation and Quality of Information on Pesticide Registration Decisions. as Measured by Gamma. ......OOOOOOOOOO......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO...... 288 Table B69. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Changes in Pest Control Costs. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ 289 Table B70. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Changes in Value of Production. as Measured by Gamma. ................................ 290 Table B71. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Other Socio-Economic Impacts. as Measured by Gamma. ......................................... 291 Table B72. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Distribution of Impacts. as Measured by Gamma. ......OOOOOOOOOOO......COOOIOOOOOOOOOOO0.... 292 Table B73. Correlations Between EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Quality of Information on Compliance. as Measured by Gamma. ................. 293 Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure 1.1 LIST OF FIGURES Idealized Timetable for the RPAR Process. ......... 14 Steps in the RPAR process and van Ravens- waay's four stages of regulatory decision making. ......OOOOOOOOOOOOOO......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 18 Groups and Routes of Pesticide Exposure. .......... 76 Mathematical Models to Determine Risk. ............ 79 Different Conceptualizations of the Real Benefits of Pesticide Use. ........................ 81 Value of Increased Quantity or Quality of Output. 0.000.000.0000.........OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO.... 83 Value of Reduced Production Costs. ................ 83 Summary of Conceptualization of Benefits and RiSks. ......OOOOOIOOO......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO.... 89 Components of Pesticide Risk Assessment and Principal Organizational Responsi- bilities in the Office of Pesticide Programs. ........................................ 143 Components of Pesticide Benefit Analysis (for a given site) and Principal Organi- zational Responsibilities in the Office of Pesticide Programs. ............................ 171 -xvi- CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION OVERVIEW A variety of chemicals are used in the U.S. food system to obtain a variety of economic benefits. Pesticides are used to improve crop quality and yields. Pharmaceuticals! are used to improve the health of livestock. Preservatives are used to reduce food spoilage and food poisoning risks. While chemical technologies provide benefits. they also pose risks to human health and the environment. Governments have responded to this situation by enacting regulatory statutes which set general policy on the use of these tech— nologies. The responsibility for carrying out these laws has been assigned to regulatory agencies. The manner in which the laws have been carried out by the agencies has created a great deal of controversy. One of the major points of criticism has focused on the way information about the tmmefits and risks of chemicals has been collected. analyzed. and used for choice-making within regulatory agencies. Agencies have been accused of being less than thorough in collecting data. arbitrary in their analysis of data. and vague about how they use infor- mation to weigh benefits and risks. A variety of reforms. such as cost-benefit analysis. have been proposed as @ AV» pa. 1.- .n. A... .5- ‘4‘ M b'u H.\h .‘\ '5 m l'. F\ nlfi f3?” potential remedies for the perceived problems. And the proposed reforms have themselves become the targets of criticism. For the most part. however. criticisms and proposed reforms have not been based on systematic. empirical information about regulatory decision processes. The objective of this research is to provide systematic. empirical information about the regulatory process of col- lecting and analyzing data (N1 the consequences of chemical technologies. Theories of regulatory decision—making are used to explain the types and quality of information ob- served in case studies of actual regulatory decisions. The research focuses on pesticide regulation. Concentration~on gone regulatory area rather than on several allows us to study the use of risk-benefit analysis between cases within a regulatory program without having to study decision making under two or more different legislative mandates and/or within two or more different agencies. Therefore. the complexities of inter—agency and inter-program behavior are avoided. The remainder of this chapter is organized under three subheadings. Under the first. the broad topic of pesticide regulation is narrowed down into a statement of the research problem emu} several research questions. thus answering the question of what it is about pesticide regulation that is to be investigated. The second section (us this chapter de- scribes the research setting by providing an overview of the -3- Environmental Protection Agency's (EPA) regulation of pesti— cides that are suspected of posing a risk to humans or other organisms in the ecosystem. The final section is a brief description of the organization of the body of the thesis. THE RESEARCH PROBLEM Research on regulation by economists tends to take one of two directions: analysis of the impacts of regulation on different groups in the economic system and analysis of the process of regulatory decision making. Although the vast majority of work by economists is of the former variety. this research is concerned with the process of regulatory decision making on pesticides. This process is essentially one of conflict-resolution. Why be concerned with such a complex process? Many people see no point in examining the process if the outcome of the process is known. However. there are at least six compelling reasons for having a knowledge of the process. First. in order to justify the resources devoted to public policy analysis. it is necessary to understand the utility of such analysis in the conflict-resolution process. Sec- ond. knowledge (M5 the process highlights points of uncer— tainty in the regulatory problem. which may help to focus on relevant issues and prioritize the use of limited policy analysis resources.l Third. desired changes in regulatory lSteven Maynard-Moody and Charles C. McClintock. ”Square Pegs in Round Holes: Program Evaluation and Organizational Uncertainty." Policy Studies Journal 9. no. 5 (Spring 1981): 644-666. ‘ _—-:——Ib-. .- . R, in ,n -hD- a... '5 . ’1 L1 . EU I!“ i nieTl‘. 4. performance can be identified (assumedly through the polit- ical process). but these changes cannot be implemented unless the variables affecting the agency decision-making process are known. .As George Stigler puts it. "Until the basic logic of political life is developed. reformers will be ill-equipped to use the state for their reforms ..."2 Fourth. a great deal of the controversy over regula— tion focuses on the process rather than the outcome per se. For example. regarding risk~related regulation such as pes— ticide regulation. there is much disagreement in the scien- tific community over how to determine risk. how to extrapo-“ late risk findings in other organisms to humans. how to translate risk into numbers of deaths or injuries. how to U weigh risk factors in decision making. and other questions of process. For all types of regulation. one often hears the argument that bureaucratic processes are inherently inefficient and counterproductive. In order to answer these charges. policy analysts need to know how decisions are being made in the face of uncertainty and limited resources. A fifth reason for investigating the process of pesticide regulation is that knowledge of the regulatory process al- lows us to predict. as well as explain. agency decisions. Predicting decisions allows more accurate analysis of 2George Stigler. ”The Theory of Economic Regulation." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2. no. 1 (Spring 1971): I8. -5- program impacts. leading to more precise policy design. Finally. knowledge of the process enables individuals or groups affected by the regulation to have a greater impact on the decision-making process (i.e.. to articulate their preferences or ideas on regulatory reform). Gaining insights about regulatory' decision making is extremely complex due to the intricacies of human psychology and sociology. Things are not always what they appear to be: Majone warns us that '[RJegulators have sought legit- imacy for their decisions by wrapping them in a cloak of 3 Samuels and Shaffer (1982) scientific respectability.“ tell us that policymakers and interested parties often invoke symbols. myths and ideology to convince others of their views. Similarly. Edelman (1977) describes how ”political language” in bureaucracy is used to justify decisions to the various conflicting groups that can impact the agency. Language is used to shape behavior within an agency and to evoke favorable perceptions of agency perfor- mance outside of the agency: ”It is not facts that are crucial. but language forms and socially cued percep- tions."4 Regulatory decisions are not cut-and-dried choices 3Giandomenico Majone. ”Process and Outcome in Regulatory Decision-Making.” American Behavioral Scientist 22. no. 5 (May/June 1979). p. 561. 4Murray Edelman. Political Language: Words that Succeed and Policies that FailVTNew York: Academic Press. 1977). p. 85. -6- based on objective calculations of net social benefits. Ultimately. they are political choices between conflicting interests. In addition. various subprocesses of risk- related decision making are characterized by what van Ravenswaay (1983) calls a "science-policy interface." That is. there are points in decision making and its subprocesses where choices are based on policy considerations rather than science. Choices can be politicized due to the nature of the choice (e.g.. choices made by weighing benefits and costs. or choices made under uncertainty and risk) or due to an inability or unwillingness to expend the funds necessary to make completely informed decisions. Whatever the reason. there is discretion in regulatory agency decision making which cannot be explained by scientific knowledge or legis- lative mandates. Adding to the complexity of the decision-making process is the fact that a number of different subprocesses combine to form the entire decision-making process. These subpro— cesses or stages include problem detection. identification of alternative solutions to the problem. identification of consequences associated with alternatives and choice between alternatives. These stages of decision-making do not neces- sarily occur in the order presented. and the extent to which each occurs varies. All four of these stages and their sub— stages contain policy (as well as science) aspects. It is the policy aspects of the third stage. the identi- fication of consequences. that this research investigates. There is an attempt to answer the following questions: -7- 1. Which consequences of pesticide use and regulation are identified? Somehow. decisions are Imuke to evaluate some impacts and not others in EPA's RPAR risk-benefit analyses.5 (hue of the objectives of this research is to determine which impacts are evaluated and to suggest reasons for the choice of impacts. 2. To what extent are the consequences evaluated? This is the heart of the empirical work contained in this thesis. The question can be worded in another way: How good is the information on consequences? The question is answered by a careful examination of EPA's "position documents" which con- stitute one of the outputs of the pesticide regulatory process. 3. Why are consequences evaluated to that extent? There is also an attempt to explain variations in the qual- ity and amount of information obtained for a particular consequence (mostly variations between uses of a pesticide). Theme is a complex array of factors that could cause this variation. but the focus here is on the influence of ex— ternal interest groups on EPA's information-gathering behavior. Chapter 2 reviews the literature on factors affecting the regulatory decision-making process. 4. Which consequences are ignored? EPA does not con- sider some of the impacts of pesticide use and regulation 5See Chapter 3 for a discussion of the value judgments involved in conceptualizing and choosing impacts for analy- sis. -8- for budgetary and other reasons. In order to determine which impacts are excluded. the risks and benefits of pesti- cide use and/or regulation must be conceptualized. This taxonomy of risks and benefits is found in Chapter 3. There are several reasons for investigating this partic- ular stage of decision making. The most obvious is the need to narrow the scope of the research in some manner in order to make it more manageable. Examining one subprocess or stage of regulatory decision making allows a reduction in scope without resulting in a superficial investigation of the entire process. Second. and perhaps most important. most of the criticisms and attempts at reform of pesticide regulation have focused on the identification of conse- quences. In fact. there have already been two major studies of pesticide regulation since the regulatory reforms of 1972.6 In both studies a policy aspect of regulatory deci- sion making on pesticides is acknowledged, but the emphasis in both is on obtaining additional and better information on the consequences of regulatory alternatives rather than on understanding how such policy choices are made or how more information affects decisions that are essentially policy choices. Many of the reforms of the pesticide regulatory process are attempts to ”objectively” reconcile the 6Environmental Studies Board Committee on Prototype Explicit Analyses for Pesticides, Regulating Pesticides (Washington. DC: National Research Council. 1980). National Research Council, Pesticide Decision-Making_ (Washington. DC: National Academy of Sciences, 1977). -9- uncertainty inherent in risk-benefit analysis: examples include a Scientific Advisory Panel (SAP) established to review assessments of the risks of pesticide use. the creation of a role for the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA) and state experts in the benefits analy- sis. and the opportunity for members of the general public to comment on EPA actions at various points in the regu- latory process. In addition. a number of proposed reforms relate to the identification of the consequences in pesti- cide regulation. In order to evaluate the validity of criticisms and the effectiveness of reforms it is essential to understand the constraints on regulatory decision mak- ing7 which limit the extent of consequence identification. even in the absence of uncertainty. A final reason for studying this stage of decision making is that knowledge about one stage of decision making is useful in understand- ing the other stages of decision making since they are interdependent. In the case of consequence identification. some theories of decision making state that decisions are (or should be) made on the basis of information on the con- sequences of alternative courses of action. If this describes actual decision making. then the identification of consequences is crucial to the choice between alternative policies. Although this is probably an overstatement of the 7See Chapter 2 for a theoretical discussion of these constraints. role of information in regulatory decision making and an understatement of the influence of other factors. there is undoubtedly a relationship between the two stages. as well as between the identification of consequences and the other two stages of regulatory decision making. Thus. this research attempts to answer two general questions —- how extensively are consequences identified for each alternative. and why? The research consists of both descriptive and explanatory work on one stage of regulatory decision making. THE RESEARCH SETTING: EPA REGULATION OF PESTICIDES The above research questions are examined in the context of the process developed by Congress and the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to determine how pesticides that pose a risk to human health and the environment should be used. The Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration , ......o at! M“. .'_ . .' ,ufisz-J “n...“ru“~fi ...- v‘O-n' “avg-«.... _..',"I . Mug“ . '9. N. .W' W (RPAR) process was developed by the EPA in response to the Federal Environmental Pesticide Control Act (FEPCA). which was a 1972 amendment to the 1947 Federal Insecticide. Fungi- cide and Rodenticide Act (FIFRA). The RPAR process is the major mechanism with which EPA makes regulatory decisions on pesticides which are suspected of causing harm to humans or other non-target organisms. The following is a brief overview of the RPAR process. Although the focus of the research is on the identification of consequences of alternative regulatory actions. a general description of the entire process is appropriate in order to :11; provide a setting for the research. given the inter— dependence of the four stages of regulatory decision making. Before 1970. while USDA still administered FIFRA. the focus of the Act was on the registration and accurate labeling of efficacious (as opposed to safe) chemicals. In response to increasing knowledge and concern about the safety of pesticides. the Act was amended in 1964 to include chemicals which injure man. other vertebrates and other organisms valuable to man in the definition of a "mis- branded" chemical. The 1964 amendments also ended "protest registration." a practice which allowed the registration of a suspected misbranded chemical and placed the burden of proving that a: chemical was ndsbranded (Hi the USDA. In- stead. the registrants now had to prove that their chemicals were safe. efficacious and/or properly branded in order to obtain registration. In 1970. the administration of FIFRA was transferred from USDA to EPA. Two years later. major changes were made in FIFRA when FEPCA was adopted. The most widely-quoted phrase in the new FIFRA summarizes the major change in philosophy contained in this amendment: EPA can register or.,/* reregister only those pesticides which "... when used in accordance with widespread and commonly recognized practice ... will not generally cause unreasonable adverse effects on . 8 the env1ronment ..." where unreasonable adverse effects on 8Federal Insecticide. Fungicide and Rodenticide Act. 7 US Code Annotated. Sec. 136(a)(5)(D). -12- the environment are "[aJny unreasonable risk to man or the environment. taking into account the economic. social and environmental costs and benefits of the use of any pesticide ... '5) These phrases signified a breaking of ties between FIFRA and the interests of farmers. No longer was the Act to solve conflicts between farmers and pesticide producers -- the arena for conflict now contained pesticide producers and farmers (Hi the one luuui versus those exposed involun- tarily to the health risks of pesticides on the other. Additional amendments to FIFRA in 1975 seemed intended to promote accurate and balanced consideration of the bene- fits and risks of pesticide use in EPA decisions on pesti- cide registration. First. the amendments provided a: role for the USDA in the benefits analysis. Also. the 1975 amendments authorized the creation of a Scientific Advisory Panel (SAP) to review the risk analysis for each pesticide. The RPAR process itself was created by EPA regulation in 1975. Initially. the process was meant to be a mechanism for finding problem pesticides. with administrative hearings used to make regulatory decisions on the problem chemicals. However. it soon became evident that EPA would like to replace lengthy hearings with the RPAR process. which was an informal and non-adversarial regulatory mechanism when compared with the administrative hearings. 9Federal Insecticide. Fungicide and Rodenticide Act. 7 US Code Annotated. Sec. 136(bb). "I- ,. v' ya 11‘) ..J b \- -13... Figure 1.1 summarizes the steps in the RPAR process in the form of an idealized timetable. This timetable has never been followed for any chemical so far in FEPCA's brief history. but it does provide a general chronology of the process. First. there is the pre-RPAR review. during which the EPA decides whether or not to begin the RPAR process for the particular pesticide in question. The decision is suppos- edly based entirely on risk. In order to make this de- cision. EPA obtains data from registrants and from the open literature. and can also require additional information (e.g.. tests on toxicity of the chemical) from registrants. From this information. EPA determines whether or not one or more specific "triggers" for various health and environmen— 10 Supposedly. EPA considersu/’// tal risks are met or exceeded. exposure levels and margins-of—safety in addition to infor— mation (N1 the toxicity (us the chemical in making the pre- liminary risk assessment. It is generally EPA procedure not to share much information with registrants during this phase of the process. Next. if EPA feels that a risk trigger has been met (as it almost always does once pre—RPAR review has begun). a Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration is published in the Federal Register. often with the supporting 10U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. "Regulations for the Enforcement of the Federal Insecticide. Fungicide and Rodenticide Act." 40 Code 2E Federal Regulations. part 162.11 (July. 1983). 29.x by by by by by by Sources: +105 +180 +210 +240 +270 +300 1. 2. -14.. Activity Pre-RPAR Review. EPA lets USDA and registrants know of its inten- tions. USDA may begin work on joint EPA/USDA/States Benefits analysis if it feels that the EPA‘s Notice of Presumption Against Registration will not be rebutted. Position Document 1 (Preliminary risk assessment) and Notice of Presumption Against Registration published in Federal Register. Development of rebuttals to PDI and Notice of Presumption Against Registration by pesticide registrants and perhaps USDA. If rebuttals are successful. then EPA publishes Position Document 2 (which terminates the RPAR process) in the Federal Register. Benefits Analysis by USDA/EPA/States. This report is used in EPA‘s risk-benefit analysis. EPA completes risk-benefit analysis. Position Document 2/3 becomes available (discusses risks. rebuttals. benefits. regulatory alterna- tives and recommended alternative). Call for public comment. Availability of PD 2/3 and Preliminary Notice of Determination published in Federal Register. Comments due from public and from the Scientific Advisory Panel (SAP evaluates the risk analysis only). Comments also due from the Secretary of Agriculture on impacts on the agricultural economy. Position Document 4 (analysis of comments and final Agency decision) published in Federal Register with Notice of Intent to Cancel. Meeting with Dr. Fred Tschirley on April 15. 1981. Environmental Studies Board Committee on Prototype Explicit Analyses for Pesticides. Regulatigg Pesti- cides. (Washington. DC: National Research Council. -15- 3. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Office of Pesticide Programs. ”Status Report on Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration (RPAR) or Special Review Chemicals. Registration Standards Program. and Data Call-In Program“ (Washington. D.C.: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. March 1984). Figure 1.1 - Idealized Timetable for the RPAR Process document. Position Document One. which is a preliminary risk assessment of the pesticide. This Notice of RPAR and Posi- tion Document One are subject to rebuttal attempts by registrants and other interested parties. The official time period allowed for rebuttal responses is 45 days from pub- lication of the Notice of RPAR. but EPA generally grants 60- day extensions. Rebuttal can be accomplished by proving that the pesticide doesn't meet the trigger(s) or by showing that exposure is low enough so that risk is not great. In addition. EPA also seems to consider rebuttal comments that show that the benefits of pesticide use are so great that the risk is worth it. Rebuttals are rarely successful. The next step. if the notice of RPAR is successfully rebutted. is the issuance of a Position Document 2 explain- ing why PDl was rebutted and the return of the pesticide in question to the registration process. If the rebuttal attempts are unsuccessful. then a risk-benefit analysis of . l b l -16- the status—quo use of the pesticide is developed. alterna— tive solutions t1) risk reduction are generated. the risk- benefit analysis is extrapolated and embellished upon for each alternative solution. and a preliminary decision is made between the alternative solutions (generally for each use of the pesticide). All of this. as well as the chemical background and regulatory history of the pesticide. and an analysis of the rebuttal comments. is contained in Position Document 2/3. which supports the Preliminary Notice of Determination published in the Federal Register. There is opportunity for external review of and comment on the Position Document 2/3 and the proposed regulatory action. Interested parties have 30 days to submit comments. but sometimes extensions are granted by EPA. In addition. the risk-benefit analysis and proposed regulatory decision are reviewed by the Secretary of Agriculture and the Scientific Advisory Panel (SAP). These two parties have 60 days from the publication of the Preliminary Notice of Determination in the Federal Register to respond. If their comments are received by EPA within 30 days. they must be published in the Federal Register with EPA's reply and the Final Notice of Determination. The Final Notice of Determination is published in the Federal Register. often with its supporting Position Document 4n Position Document 4 replies to comments from the Secretary of Agriculture. the SAP and others. and ex- plains the rationale for the final Agency decision. Omce -17- this document is published. cancellation activities can begin.11 After this step. the RPAR process is complete and the only recourse for interested parties is administrative hearings. The details of the process are still very much in a developmental stage. as can be evidenced by reforms proposed by EPA in the August 7. 1980. Federal Register and more recent proposals to attempt to negotiate solutions to risk problems with pesticide manufacturers instead of undertaking the benefits analysis. Figure 2 shows how the steps of the RPAR process corre- spond with the four stages of decision making. There are some additional aspects of the identification of conse— quences stage which should be noted since that stage is the focus of the research. The EPA obtains much of its infor- mation from parties outside of the agency. such as the USDA. state experts and the registrants. Many of these external parties have a vested interest in the outcome of the regula- tory process. and they may have an influence on the process due to their control over information. Two different divi— sions of the EPA's Office of Pesticide Programs collect and analyze data for the risk and benefit assessments. The risk analysis is performed by the Hazard Evaluation Division and the benefits analysis is performed by the Benefits and Field 11"Conditional Cancellation“ means that a particular use of the chemical will be banned if changes in labeling and/or use practices are not made. "Unconditional Cancellation" means that the chemical is banned. Steps in the RPAR Process Pre-RPAR Review Notice of Presumption Against Registration and Position Document 1 Rebuttal attempts and public comments If successful rebuttal. Position Document 2 and return to registration USDA/EPA/States Benefits Analysis and EPA risk-benefit analysis Position Document 2/3 and Preliminary Notice of Determination Public Comments Position Document 4 Source: -13- Stages of Decision Making Problem Detection: Identifi- cation of Consequences Problem Detection: Identifi- cation of Consequences Problem Detection: Identifi- fication of Consequences Choice Between Alternatives (alternatives = return to registration and initiate RPAR Process) Identification of Consequences Generation of Alternative Solutions: Identification of Consequences: Choice Between Alternatives Identification of Consequences: perhaps Problem Detection and Generation of Alternative Solutions Choice Between Alternatives Compiled by the author. Figure 1.2 — Steps in the RPAR process and van Ravenswaay's four stages of regulatory decision making. -19- Studies Division (in conjunction with USDA and State ex- perts). A third division. the Special Pesticide Review Division (SPRD). has overall responsibility for coordinating ”fl-ww4m-Mwm. implementation of the RPAR process and also supervises the weighing of risks and benefits and recommends a regulatory Option tx> the Deputy Assistant Administrator for Pesticide Programs (who ultimately answers to the Administrator of the EPA). The common thread throughout the risk-benefit analy- sis for a particular pesticide is the project manager. who is from the SPRD. However. the final decision is technic- ally the responsibility of the Administrator: thus. the situation is one in which information on the consequences of alternative regulatory options is not generated by the final decision maker. One of the outputs of the RPAR process. aside from the regulatory decision. is time set of position documents for each pesticide which goes through the process. These doc- uments provide information supporting various actions taken by the Agency. from the initial rebuttable presumption through the final decision. These position documents con- tain information on the consequences of full use of a pesti- cide and of alternative regulatory actions. Thus. the position documents for 13K; eight pesticides for which the RPAR process had been completed at the commencement of the empirical work serve as the data base for the work on conse- quence identification. One limitation of the use of the position documents as the data base is that all consequences -20- which are considered may not be in the position documents. However. it is still of value (as discussed in the previous subsection) to know which consequences are identified. why. and whether or not the consequences identified appear to have any bearing on the choice between regulatory alterna- tives. ORGANIZATION OF THE THESIS The remainder of this thesis is organized as follows: Chapter 2 consists of a review of the theoretical liter- ature on regulatory decision-making processes. Some of the works examined in this chapter serve as the basis for the explanatory variables conceptualized and operationalized to explain EPA's identification of consequences in pesticide decision making. Chapter(g:is a conceptualization of the risks and bene- fits of pesticide use. The intent of this chapter is to provide a comprehensive taxonomy of risks and benefits to serve as a basis of comparison with EPA's taxonomy of risks and benefits. Chapter 4 describes the methodology used in coding data and testing relationships about EPA identification of conse— quences in the RPAR process. The data set consists of the position documents for eight pesticides for which RPARs have been completed. Chapteq:§)is the first empirical chapter. consisting of an analysis of the descriptive statistics and explanatory work on the risks of pesticide use. -21- Chapter 6 presents the results of empirical work on the benefits of pesticide use. Chapterflcontains results. conclusions and directions for future research. CHAPTER 2 THEORIES OF THE REGULATORY PROCESS: A REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE INTRODUCTION There is an immense body of literature from many differ- ent disciplines on various aspects of regulatory agency de- cision making. The objective of this chapter is to organize and summarize some of this diverse literature to help in describing. explaining and predicting the EPA's behavior with regard to pesticide regulation. The literature review is organized under four subheadings: the nature of regula- tion. theories of regulatory decision making. the role of information in decision making. and the usefulness of the theories in explaining the quality of information obtained by EPA to evaluate consequences of pesticide use or regula- tion.12 THE NATURE OF REGULATION Several authors have explored the nature of regulation in general. as mandated and implemented. rather than details 12Other reviews of the literature on regulation are con- tained in Noll (1976). Posner (1974). McCraw (1975). Fiorino and Metlay (1977). Owen and Braeutigam (1978). Mueller (1979) and Mitnick (1980). -22- 56' CO OJ C) be -23- of regulatory decision making. The readings discussed below do not constitute a random sample of this literature -- three of the four works are written by institutional econo- mists. However. the articles suffice in presenting a pic- ture of regulation which is not commonly considered in the literature of neoclassical welfare economics. Regulation is seen as the outcome of a power struggle for rights between competing interests. the product of the value system of some dominant class. or a response to an inappropriate balance between equity and efficiency. rather than as a mechanism for achieving greater economic efficiency within the status quo system of rights. This literature provides a view of regulation which supports the work of many of the theorists in the next section. who concern themselves more with the political realities of regulatory decision making and its attendant impacts than with unconstrained decision making with the goal of economic efficiency. Paul Weaver (1978). a non-institutionalist (and also a non-economist). feels that the nature of regulation has changed over time. but that it is and always has been the manifestation of the values of a particular dominant class. The 'old" decision making (e.g.. airlines. public utili— ties). characterized by the “iron triangle" -- a coalition of the regulated industry. the regulatory agency or commis- sion. and the Congressional subcommittees responsible for legislative hearings and oversight -- was a reflection of the values of the liberal democratic class which dominated (* £1) "h 'V r“ -24- national thought at the time of the enactment of the enabl- ing legislation. The "new" decision making. which is not explained by the capture theories of regulation or by most empirical work. is a result of the humanistic values charac- teristic of a new dominant class. This regulation includes much of the health and safety and income maintenance regula- tion. and Weaver claims that the new iron triangle is com- prised of the press. public interest groups and the Federal government. Weaver sees regulation as social policy rather than economic policy. Indeed. That is why all economists. whatever their political views. end up being so critical of government regulation. at least as it works out in practice. They think regulatory policy should make sense economicall31y -- which. of course. it never quite does. Weaver is wrong. Although many economists see the purpose of regulation as correcting "market imperfections" ix! an economically efficient manner. and judge regulation accordingly. not all do. Among those who do not are the following institutional economists. who attempt to describe the regulatory process in a positive manner in terms of the relationship between institutions (common and statutory law. regulation. customs. morals. et cetera) and economics, Reynolds (1981) criticizes some of his fellow economists for judging regulations which are a response to efficiency 13Paul Weaver. "Regulation. Social Policy. and Class Conflict." The Public Interest 50 (Winter 1978): 56. r' (ll CT 4 V‘ (I) '1 III LA) -25- and/or equity problems in terms of efficiency alone. Like Weaver. he notices variations in regulation depending on the time of the enactment of the enabling legislation. The old regulation (basically pre-l970) is industry-specific and attempts to achieve the desired allocational or distribu- tional goals by augmenting revenues of the regulated group. Such regulation is typically demanded (and captured) by firms. industry groups (n: trade associations. Function- specific regulation (post-1969) is seen by Reynolds as often being a response to the industry-specific regulation's impacts on equity and/or efficiency. However. this type of regulation affects costs rather than revenues of the firms or other regulated groups. When describing the industry-specific and function- specific regulation. Reynolds is describing two types of explicit regulation. Explicit regulation consisms of the implementation and enforcement of statutory and common law chosen in the political process. whereas implicit regulation refers to informal "laws" such as habits. norms. ethics and values. The entire system of regulation in Reynolds' world is affected by and affects technology. The system needs to be a combination of implicit and explicit regulation which exhibits some degree of companionship with the technological and physical world. If this compatibility does not exist. then the regulatory system will change. Compatibility is essentially an appropriate (socially acceptable) balance V“ T‘ ... U] (”f (D (T ’1 T‘ U) ’k! —26- between equity and efficiency and an adequate level of flexibility. It is a function of the legislation. sup- porting institutions. and "escapements" in the regulation (mechanisms which result in distorted perceptions of the relationship between compliance with and impacts or costs of the regulation). Sudden perceptions of market failure are really responses to social and ethical changes. and/or the loss of escapements for existing regulation. Changes in the regulatory system comprise a life cycle. In general. Reynolds sees implicit regulation evolving over the long run. If the implicit regulation fails to produce socially acceptable allocative and distributive impacts. then revenue-augmenting (industry-specific) regulation is established.14 In response to new allocations an distri- butions. other groups may attempt to obtain their own revenue-augmenting regulation to offset costs of the revenue-augmenting regulation of others. Function-specific regulation is often a response to perceived inadequacies of industry-specific regulations. Finally. the current popular support for "deregulation" is aa response to changes which have made the function-specific regulation unacceptable. Reynolds' regulatory system is dynamic and it determines and is determined by technological progress. Samuels. Schmid. and Shaffer (1981) also see the regula- tory system as dynamic and as a dependent and explanatory 14Explicit regulation usually overrules implicit regula- tion. -2'7- variable in larger systems. in) these economists. the cen- tral issue in regulatory decision making is not which form of regulation is 'best' or the efficiency of regulation. but rather "whose interests are to be promoted by regulation and how...,"15 for regulation restricts the opportunity set of some individuals while expanding or improving opportunities for others. As implemented. regulation (and changes in reg- ulation) are rights in that both regulations and rights distribute costs, benefits and risk among interdependent parties. In a broader context. regulation both exists in and determines a power structure. It is only one of many forms of social control which are intended to achieve a balance between freedom and control. hierarchy and equality. and continuity and change. Various groups within a power struc- ture try to use government to achieve regulation in their favor. Both "public" and “private" regulations free some individuals at the expense of others (albeit different individuals); they are merely alternative ways of achieving social control. According to the authors. ”Arguments over regulation concern the pattern of freedom versus exposure to 15Warren J. Samuels. A. Allan Schmid and James D. Shaffer. “Regulation and Regulatory Reform: Some Funda- mental Conceptions' in Law and Economics: An Institutional Perspective. eds. Warren J. Samuels and A. Allan Schmid (Boston: Martinus Nijhoff Publishing. 1981). p. 248. -28- the freedoms of others .... made by power-playing actors participating in the drama of working out social con- trol."16 Samuels and Shaffer (1982) continue this theme in their paper on deregulation. In this paper. they attempt to show that eight arguments commonly put forth in favor of deregu- lation are normative arguments and are inconclusive. Some of the major points in the paper are that deregulation and regulation are funtionally the same in that both protect rights (different people's rights). deregulation represents a restructuring (n3 rights. only selective perception makes deregulation distinct from rights. to say that regulation and/or deregulation are good or bad requires normative judg- ments. both regulation and deregulation require coercion of those whose opportunity sets are restricted. and definitions of output (which are determined by regulation and deregula- tion) determine whether or not deregulation promotes produc- tivity and efficiency along with the set of rights used to determine the efficient or Pareto-optimal allocation of resources (which is also determined by regulation and dereg- ulation). All of these writings on the nature of regulation are based on the general theme that regulatory decisions are political as well as scientific. Decisions do not simply fall out of the analysis of benefit and cost information. nor does the regulatory process revolve around the gathering l6IbidoI p. 255. -29- of objective information. This has strong implications for decision making in general and for the identification of consequences of regulatory decisions in particular. The next section of this chapter is an attempt to move from the general to the specific by summarizing different theories on the factors which influence the regulatory process and its output. THEORIES OF REGULATORY DECISION MAKING Regulation theorists need to address two major questions if they are to provide information on the regulatory decision-making process: what are the goals (objective functions) of regulators. and what factors constrain the achievement of those goals? The theorists answer these questions 511 different ways. In order ix) facilitate the discussion of this diverse group of theories. the works are organized according to the hypothesized objective functions of the regulators. The theories can be classified under the subheadings of theories with .agency-wide objective func- tions. theories with different objective functions for various coalitions within an agency and theories with dif- ferent objective functions for individual regulators in the agency. Theories With Agency-Wide Objective Functions. Some theorists assume that agency goals dominate the behavior of individual regulators within the agency. This behavioral assumption has some validity. and perhaps good explanatory power since agency leaders (as well as managers in the -30- private sector) have mechanisms to encourage individuals to adopt agency goals. Also. such assumptions simplify the study of agency decision making by ignoring individual aberrations from agency goals. Agency survival. Several theorists assert that there is a link between voter behavior and agency behavior. That link is the elected politician whose fate is determined by the voter and who. in turn. determines the fate of the agency. Legislators and other elected officials have power over agency officials via appropriations. program authoriza- tion. appointments and legislative oversight (see Thurber (1976)).17 Thus. the agency officials try to make decisions which improve the number of votes. size of the campaign chest. and perhaps personal wealth of the politician. One of the more interesting theories of this type was formulated by one University of Chicago professor and ex- tended and formalized by another. Nobel prize-winner George Stigler (1971) is really explaining legislative creation in his work cut economic regulation. but Sam Peltzman extends Stigler's work to agency decision making by assuming that voters will express dissatisfaction with agency decisions by voting against the elected politicians who appointed the agency officials. Voters and regulatory agencies are linked 17Thurber also hypothesizes that the agency-elected official relationship may be one of cooperation rather than confrontation. -31- because agency officials require elected politicians' support in order to perpetuate their activities. It is con- ceivable that this hypothesis applies to the EPA since the environmental lobby influences a large number of voters and is politically sophisticated. the environmental groups are often opposed by industry groups that are also well organ— ized and powerful. and legislators are often rather clearly for or against government programs for environmental pro- tection. Stigler suggests that regulathmi is often obtained by (and for) industry due to the nature of the "market" for regulation. The regulatory market is different from the economic market in that the output must be adhered to (in principle. anyway) by everyone. If all regulatory decisions were made democratically (i.e.. by voting). then policies which resulted in more gainers than losers would be adopted. assuming perfectly informed and rational voting. Why. then. do regulations often seem to benefit fewer people than they hurt? The answer has to do with the nature of the market for regulation. People do not vote on all issues: instead they elect representatives to vote on issues. These representatives and their political parties (and. if extended one step further. the agencies) are the suppliers of regulation. Regulation is demanded by industry and other groups in Stigler’s model because it results in the redistribution of wealth and income. and it is paid for with votes and dollars for the politician. Thus. in order -32- to pay for regulation with the required number of votes and/or dollars. voters must incur the costs of informing themselves on an issue. organizing to articulate their preferences and persuading others to support (or not oppose) 18 They will only the politician supplying the regulation. incur these costs if the benefits from obtaining the favor- able regulation exceed the costs. As the size of the group demanding regulation increases. the per capita benefits decrease and the costs of organization and persuading other voters increase. The free-rider problem also increases with size -- firms may expect other firms within the industry to pay for beneficial regulation from which no already-existing firm can be excluded. Since costs increase and benefits de- crease with size. smaller groups with an economic incentive to precisely articulate their demand (such as industry groups) may be the only demanders of regulation according to Stigler. Peltzman (1972) formalizes and generalizes Stigler's theory. He explicitly establishes the voter-agency link by making note of the power of the President and Congress to appoint. agency' officials euui the resulting potential for these elected officials tx> be held accountable for agency performance. The goal of regulators is to maximize votes and/or resources for elected representatives in order to 18Bartlett (1973) develops a framework which shows how groups may subsidize information on the outcomes of policy to other groups in order to influence perceptions of the policy. -33- assure agency survival. Resources are assumed by Peltzman to be used by politicians to diffuse opposition to regula— tion. Peltzman's mathematical model solves for the vote- maximizing sizes of the groups to be benefited and taxed as well as the vote-maximizing distribution of benefits and costs among groups. The variables which explain the regu- lators' decisions on distribution of benefits and costs include the wealth of the winning and losing groups. the groups' responses (in terms of votes and resources) to taxation or benefits. and the sizes of the winning and losing groups. Thus. in order to maximize votes for the politician. the agency decision must reflect each group's relative power to affect the politician and. ultimately. the agency. If there is no opposition to a policy and if all beneficiaries will vote for the politician. then size be- comes the dominant factor. However. if there is opposition anui if votes are difficult to deliver. beneficiaries must expend resources to obtain votes (i.e.. organize and articu- late preferences) and mitigate opposition. so wealth of the groups becomes important. The explanatory variables in the decision on the sizes of benefiting and losing groups include the amount of sup- port for the regulation. the amount of opposition. and the costs of organization facing the different groups. Several general conclusions can be drawn from Peltzman's model. First. even if one group obtains all of the benefits -34- of the regulation. the groups would have obtained more benefits if a cartel had been formed without help from the government. The reason for this phenomenon in Peltzman's model is that regulators must account for the political power of opposing groups in order to maximize votes: the vote maximizing distribution of benefits and costs of regu- lation is determined by equating marginal political costs (to the regulator) and marginal political benefits. Second. Peltzman concludes from his model that there may be more than one group of beneficiaries if regulators can supply different levels of benefits to individual voters according to their sensitivity to benefits or taxes. In fact. tax- sensitive members of the losing group may actually benefit from the regulation while insensitive members of the winning group may be taxed. Stigler's theory. which proposes that the regulated industry is the only winning group. is a special case of Peltzman's general theory. Other theories hypothesizing agency-wide goals of vote- maximization are very similar to the Peltzman-Stigler theories. although not as precisely stated. Owen and Braeutigam also assume crucial links between voters. Congress and regulatory agencies. According to this theory. voters wish to obtain regulation to protect their wealth in the face of technological and economic change (Stigler and Peltzman. in focusing on economic regulation. see regulation as a means of increasing wealth). In other words. voters wish to take some of the risk out of the -35- marketplace. This desire is communicated to the agencies by Congress and voters via administrative law. which slows change. allows all interested parties to voice their con- cerns. and protects the status quo.19 Therefore. if regulatory agencies want Congressional support. they must protect voters from sudden changes in income or wealth. Administrative law helps to ensure this protection. This result is essentially equivalent to Peltzman's result that the winners in the regulatory process cannot receive all potential gains due to the necessity for regulators to account for conflicting interests. Owen and Braeutigam weaken the link between the agency and the voter by suggesting that other theories of regulation may be usefully interjected into their framework to explain discre- tionary agency behavior. John Baldwin's (1975) theory likewise makes a connection between the agency. elected officials and voters. Bureau- crats are assumed to be self-interested with a dominant goal of agency perpetuation. which is accomplished by helping to ensure the re-election of the incumbent government. Since regulation imposes costs on some groups. the agency's role is to establish an agreement between conflicting interests. Regulators thus attempt to choose the regulatory alternative with costs that can be disguised from the losers (resulting 19This is an example of ”voice" as described in Hirsch- man (1970). -36- in fewer lost votes to the incumbent government). This con- clusion is consistent with the Peltzman and Stigler models. which predict decisions resulting in diffuse costs and concentrated benefits. Baldwin acknowledges the existence of agency behavior independent of the incumbent government when he suggests that some agency support may come from outside of the government. A goal which is related to vote-maximization is that of conflict-minimization. The conflict-minimization theorists take a somewhat broader view of external pressures on agen- cies than (k) the vote-maximization theorists. and conflict minimization may imply efforts to avoid opposition rather than to seek support. In fact. efforts to disguise costs as suggested by Baldwin may actually point more toward conflict minimization than vote maximization. However. the general idea is still the same. The agency is seen as being subject to pressures from the courts. the media. other agencies and interest groups. as well as from elected officials. In order to maintain the agency. regulators attempt to minimize conflict from these sources. Paul Joskow (1974) points out that agencies are gener— ally given a good deal of flexibility in decision making with regard to the intent of a mandate. the method of achieving the intent and procedures for implementing the method. Constraints of due process from the courts and the legislature limit this discretion somewhat. Regulatory behavior is also constrained by the agency environment. -37- which consists of interactions between the agency and groups affected by regulatory decisions. Regulators experience pressures from other participants in the regulatory process -- consumer groups may act as "intervenors" during the regulatory process or exert pressure on the agency outside of the formal process. and regulated firms are also in contact with the agency during the formal process as well as on an informal basis. According to Joskow. an agency can be in equilibrium with its environment if procedures and regulatory instru- ments have been developed to balance the conflicting interests. or the agency can tmezhi the "innovation mode." during which a search for procedures and instruments to restore equilibrium occurs. Factors which create an impetus for change in the regulatory process include economic factors (e.g.. industry changes. inflation) and political factors (e.g.. the environmental movement. civil rights movement). These changes modify the relative power and the nature of the various interests in the regulatory process. Thus. the theory is similar to Peltzman's in terms of ex- planatory variables. Richard Posner (1971) implicitly assumes some sort of conflict-minimization or vote-maximization goal for agencies when he describes the rationale for the cross-subsidization forfll of ‘regulation. Internalr- or’ cross-subsidization. is regulation which results in the production of goods or ser- vices at lower prices or in larger amounts than what would _38- have been produced in the absence of regulation. The result is that some people pay (are taxed) so that others can obtain goods at subsidized prices. Posner hypothesizes that cross—subsidization is popular with regulators as an instrument for redistributive policy due to its low visibility relative to direct taxes (again. the Stigler-Peltzman theme of dispersed costs). the diffi- culty of judicial review. relatively low administrative costs and implementation without need for Congressional approval. This type of regulation scores high marks with regulated firms because it often results in entry control. and comprehensive enforcement of prices and quantities of goods is difficult. In Posner's theory. regulators appear to make regulatory decisions which balance conflicting interests in response to environmental pressures. All of the preceding theories contain some common ele— ments. All. of course. retain the agency goal of survival via vote-maximization or conflict-minimization. In addi- tion. they all suggest that constraints on goal attainment include pmessures 1J1 the agency's external environment —- namely. pressures from conflicting interests. courts. legis- lators and/or the executive branch. Thus. if these theories represent a realistic abstraction of regulatory agency behavior. relevant explanatory variables of regulatory decision making would include the power of groups in the regulatory process to impact the agency. .vu Cu in. St} -3g- Budget-maximizing, or size-maximizing, agencies. Another important set of theories with agency-wide goals is based on the assumption that regulators want to maximize agency size. budget or influence. There are two rationales for assuming this goal: some theorists feel that agency survival is assured not by maximizing votes for legislators or balancing conflicting interests. but rather by more actively trying to increase agency size over time: and other theorists believe that agency size and/or scope is tied to goals of individual regulators. such as salary. prestige. power or job security. These theories do not necessarily invalidate the theories described in the previous section: instead. they may better explain regulatory decision making at certain points in an agency's history. For example. it may be that the EPA was a "growth" agency during much of the 19703 when there was a great demand for environmental pro- tection. but that it is currently a "conflict-minimization" or "survival" agency in the face of recession. Warren Samuels (1973) believes that regulators seek to increase agency authority or power as a means of achieving their own individual goals. such as maximization of income. status or power. The main constraint in his model is the power of others to affect regulators' decisions. However. the power structure not only determines decisions but is also determined by previous decisions. Thus. the system of regulatory decision making is a struggle between interested parties to obtain favorable -4Q- legislation or regulation. .A group's strategy is often to attempt to make its particular goals the goals of the agency: Rational decision—making would seem to require well-defined. precise. agreed— upon objectives and goals of regulation. and the absence of same in regulation has been widely lamented. But a heterogen- eous institution leads ix) ambiguous statements of purpose and goals because of the continuing jockeying for position as parties-in-interest compete to have their particular goals become the goals of the institution and to revise the statutory goals. the intermediate ends and the working rules in their interests. With multiple. competing goals and criteria advanced by competing parties- in-interest. clear euui consistent goals or solutions are not permanently possi- ble. as all are subject to continual revision inzfipe corner or another of the institution. In furthering its own goals. then. the agency must be re- sponsive to the power and goals of conflicting interests. Other variables in Samuels' general equilibrium system which affect and are affected by decision making include working rules (institutions which control the distribution and use of power). the system of values (regulatory impacts may be capitalized into asset values while those values are used in making decisions). the structure of opportunity sets of various interested groups. ideology. preferences. indi— vidual choice. resource allocation and distribution of 20Warren J. Samuels. "Public Utilities and the Theory of Power" in Perspectives in Public Regulation: Essays on Political Economy. ed. Milton Russell (Carbondale. I11: Southern Illinois University Press. 1973). p. 10. -41- income and wealth. These variables. in defining the power structure. help to explain regulatory decisions. There are similarities between Samuels' approach and that of Peltzman. Both theorists stress the importance of economic and political power and the ability of groups to organize. given the structure of benefits and costs of action. Both recognize the advantage of regulated indus- tries in the power struggle. But Samuels' theory is a much more comprehensive conceptualization of regulatory decision making. Peltzman. by his own admission. does not attempt to describe the determinants of the power which he suggests explains regulatory decision making. Samuels. on the other hand. provides a general equilibrium model of the determi- nants of power as well as its impacts on regulatory decision making. William Niskanen (1975) develops a theory of the supply of government output based on two major assumptions: agen— cies strive to maximize their budgets. and both suppliers (agencies) and demanders (government review groups) of regulation are monopolistic. The latter assumption provides a bilateral monopoly situation in the market for regulation and establishes the agency-elected official link favored by so many other theorists. However. Niskanen does not feel that the link is so complete that the goals of the elected officials are directly transferred to the agency. Instead. the power of elected officials serves as a constraint on agency' attainment (M5 the budget-maximization. goal. along -42- with other factors which determine the reward structures of bureaucrats. Niskanen's major conclusion is that monopolis- tic agencies overproduce and overspend relative to the demand for the good or service produced by regulation when the agency goal is budget maximization and when a monopolis- tic review committee is the demander of regulation. Shapiro and Shelton (1977) suggest that agency size is related to personal goals of regulators. particularly salary. so they assume that the agency-wide goal is to in- crease agency size. Agency discretion in the attainment of this goal is constrained by relationships with other groups in the regulatory process. such as legislators. taxpayers. the executive branch and beneficiaries of regulation. According to this theory. agency officials attempt to make decisions which garner support from beneficiaries of the decision. facilitate re-electhmi of elected officials and disperse costs of the regulation so that taxpayers perceive the costs as being lower than the costs of Opposing the regulatory decision. These are tflue same factors that are emphasized in the theories of Stigler and Peltzman. Downing and Brady (1979) also assume that bureaucrats are interested in increasing agency responsibility in order to increase their own income and power and to further speci- fic agency goals. They suggest that politicians have goals of re-election. upward mobility and the furthering of some concept of the public interest: firm managers try to in— crease their own real incomes by increasing firm profits and -43- stock values: and consumer group leaders desire changes in property rights which reflect their ideas of equity. Choices by these groups are constrained by income and by the costs of action. Rational behavior involves bargaining with other groups for votes. contributions and/or resource transfers. Trades affecting the benefits and costs of policy decisions are made between groups in order to mutu— ally improve their situations. There also may be attempts to change the costs of action faced by groups favoring or opposing policies which affect a particular group's welfare. McKenzie and Macaulay (1980) assume a primary agency goal of increasing size and domain. Regulators attain this goal kn: making decisions which decrease efficiency in the private sector in order to make the public sector look relatively efficient. For example. monopolization of the private sector raises the price of privately-produced goods relative to public sector substitutes. Constraints on this type of behavior by the agency are not discussed in the article. The implication is that costs of action to one group are related to the power of other groups in the reg- ulatory process. Summary -- theories with agencijide objective functions. The major contribution of the preceding theories to this research is to develop the concept of interest group power as an explanatory variable for regulatory decision making. The Peltzman model is particularly precise in its description of how various characteristics of groups in the -44- regulatory process affect the nature of the regulatory process. and thus proves very useful in hypothesizing rela- tionships between explanatory and dependent variables. Theories Assuming Different Goals Within an Agency3 Another group of theorists hypothesizes that individual reg- ulators or coalitions of regulators have unique. multiple- argument objective functions. These theorists believe that attempts to aggregate individual behavior on the basis of some dominant goal do not result in accurate explanations of decision making. However. this argument is not adopted in this research. Individual or coalition goals which vary from an agency-wide goal may account for unexplained vari— ations between observed agency behavior and behavior predicted by one of the theories in the previous section. but it is assumed here that good explanatory power is ob- tained from models with agency-wide goals (especially when considering the relative simplicity of these models). for many of the same reasons that firm—wide objective functions have proven useful in the theory of the firm. Furthermore. there is no reason why individual goals couldn't be incor- porated into one of the theories with agency-wide goals to improve its explanatory power in future research -- the two views are not necessarily mutually exclusive. Since the choice in this research is to place more emphasis on agency- wide objective functions. the following theories will be described with more brevity than the preceding theories. -45- Coalitions of regulators. Wilson and Downs are the major proponents of a group of theories in which individual regulators are assumed to have objective functions which are similar enough for the regulators to be categorized into discrete groups of individuals with common goals. In James Q. Wilson's theory (1980). there are three types of bureaucrats. Careerists look to agency success for their own personal success. Their primary goal is to main- tain the agency. which is accomplished by cultivating 21 An example of political support and avoiding scandals. the latter strategy appears in Wilson's book: ”In regula- ting pesticides. EPA is keenly aware that if a product it has registered is later shown to produce cancer on a large scale. the agency will be crucified and the careers of all "22 Careerists in concerned blighted. if not destroyed. agencies learn through reinforcement to accommodate people who will use errors against them. Politicians in an agency have long-term goals of upward mobility outside of the agency which will result in finan- cial rewards and desirable career patterns. Therefore. they want to be as visible as possible to potential future em- ployers. 2J'Careerists appear to be the pure form of bureaucrats described in the theories with agency-wide objective func- tions. 2James Q. Wilson. The Politics of Regulation (New York: Basic Books. Inc.. 1980). p. 375. -46- Finally. there are _professionals. in ‘Wilson's typical agency. who obtain utility from others in the same profes- sion. Individuals in the same professions have similar ways of looking at the world. so they are likely to form coali- tions within an agency. When there are individuals from several different professions in an agency. such as in the EPA. decision making may be greatly influenced by the pro- fession which dominates. The behavior of the three types of regulators is influ- enced by certain key characteristics of the environment within which regulatory decisions are made. Wilson believes that technological enui economic change. institutions. and politics and ideas (e.g.. access to the gmflitical system. the media and friendly legislators) are three important characteristics of the regulatory environment. Anthony Downs (1965) also delineates several different groups of regulators according to their goals. Climbers and Conservers behave only according to personal goals. Climb- ers attempt to maximize their own power. income and prestige by obtaining promotions. movimg to better jobs outside of the agency or increasing the prestige and power of their current positions. Conservers. on the other hand. maximize security and convenience. and thus are very much interested in protecting the status quo. Other regulators pursue both personal and collective goals: mixed-motive officials in- clude zealots. advocates and statesmen. Zealots devote -47- their collective energies ix) narrow issues. whereas advo- cates fight for particular organizations or policy areas. Statesmen support the broadest collective group -- they maintain goals relevant to society as a whole in their objective functions. In considering variables affecting agency decision making. Downs feels that the internal structural variables of an organization cannot be considered separately from variables describing the external environment within which an agency operates. Some of the internal and external variables contained in his hypotheses on agency behavior include information costs. capability of decision makers. degree of uncertainty. degree of information distortion and conformity of lower-level bureaucracy to agency goals (both affected by the degree of hierarchy in the agency). time constraints. bias of decision makers. degree of coordination between agencies with overlapping duties. degree of goal homogeneity between individual regulators. the age (M5 the agency and the agency's rate of growth. Thus. decision making is influenced by the internal structure of the agency. which determines and is determined by the agency's external environment. Unique objective functions for individual regula- tors. The models which hypothesize unique objective functions for individual regulators are more complex and less definitive than those which assume an agency-wide objective function. However. they may result in greater ~48- explanatory power. The following is a brief summary of some of these theories. The theories are not necessarily in conflict with the Stigler-Peltzman and other theories: instead. they may explain some of the deviation of actual decision making from decision making predicted by theories with agency-wide objective functions. Roger Noll (1971a) assumes that individual regulators maximize unique objective functions which may contain the regulator's welfare. agency maintenance and/or growth.23 and the welfare of groups and individuals impacted by the reg- ulators' decisions. Noll downplays somewhat the Congress— agency link. Although he feels that Congress is able to influence decision making. he also believes that the budget of a single agency is such a small portion of the total. complex federal budget that Congress is not particularly informed or concerned about individual decisions in an agency when making budget decisions. Like Stigler and Peltzman and many others. Noll sees the power of interest groups. dependent on benefits and costs of group activity. as affecting decisions. The tendency to overcompromise so that all interested parties "gain" some- thing (as in Peltzman's theory) results in a sacrifice of the "social optimum" iJI‘Noll's mind. The degree of con- troversy is hypothesized to be directly related to the 23It is conceivable that an agency could be growing dur- ing one time period (e.g.. EPA in early 19705) and struggle for maintenance during another time period (EPA now?). _49- length of time it takes an agency to reach a decision. the amount of information search. the shifting of responsibility for the decision and the costs of access to the agency by interested parties. The latter strategy for diffusing con- troversy may backfire if interest groups bypass the agency anui go directly to Congress. thus increasing Congressional pressure on the agency. Many of these ideas are reiterated in Noll (1971b). Marc Roberts (1975) has formulated a framework of the variables which explain the decision outcomes of private and public organizations. In an effort to explain how individ— ual decisions are translated into an cmganization's deci- sions. Roberts classifies explanatory variables into fcmr groups: variables describing the agency's external environ- ment. the internal structure of the organization. the set of rewards and punishments which control an individual's behav- ior within the organization and individual beliefs and goals. Roberts feels that (flue "external variables" are less important than "internal variables" in explaining organiza- tional decision making. which is counter to most of the other theories examined thus far. However. this hypothesis may be less true for government agencies requiring legisla- tive and taxpayer support than for organizations which do not have to account to external constituencies. -5o- Shaffer (1979) identifies several groups as participants in the regulatory process: government (including the legis- lature and the bureaucracy). consumers. the media and pro- ducers of ruwhmegulation goods. The individuals in these groups have their own sets of goals and operate in an en- vironment constrained tar the institutional structure. ideology. physical constraints and uncertainty. These con- straints on decision making both determine behavior and are determined by prior behavior in the political-economic system. Government suppliers of regulation have different goals and face unique environments. and may not be held responsi- ble for decisions since much government output is unmeasur- able. Regulators seek information on the preferences of those groups which demand regulation. As Stigler. Peltzman and others recognize. it may be costly for some individuals or groups to make their preferences known to regulators. but Shaffer extends this concept by suggesting that there is a market for information on preferences. Thus. the suppliers of this information are able to influence the regulatory process. Ross Eckert (1973) attempts to explain decision making with alternative internal structures of regulatory bodies (an agency structure and a commission structure) in an empirical study of taxicab regulation. He specifically examines how different incentive structures facing commis- sioners and agency officials result in different choices. -51_ Eckert assumes that regulators rationally maximize utility. with utility a function of multiple variables such as wealth. prestige and convenience. Commissioners usually have a legislatively-determined income independent of hours worked or difficulty of duties. whereas agency officials may obtain salary increases as the scope and complexity of their tasks increase. Therefore. commissioners may generate more utility by simplifying tasks while agency officials may max- imize utility by increasing the agency budget or the number of firms regulated. Eckert presents data on commission and agency regulation of taxicabs which tentatively support his ideas. Kohlmeier (1973) sheds some light on the informal regu- latory process -- specifically. with regard to private meetings between regulators and the regulated. If the regulators' objective functions include future» employment within the regulated industry or avoidance of adverse industry-wide publicity against the agency. then private meetings may impact regulatory decisions. Theories assuming unique individual objective functions usually result in fewer definitive conclusions than the theories assuming individual conformity to agency-wide goals. Although the former group of theories may have greater explanatory power. their use in applied research may be difficult due to problems in measuring the variables. determining individuals' objective functions. and aggrega- ting individual behavior to make a statement about agency behavior. -52- THE USE OF INFORMATION IN REGULATORY DECISION MAKING If it is acknowledged that regulators operate in a political setting and have goals other than maximizing net benefits to society. then it becomes necessary to examine the role of policy analysis and its resultant benefit-cost information in regulatory decision making in order to under- stand why the information is of a particular quality. This section of the chapter examines the issues of whether more information leads to better decisions. the characteristics of regulators' information searches anui the various hypo- thesized roles of information in regulatory decision making. Is More Information Better? Many economists believe that with enough information. a decision will "fall out" of an economic analysis.24 but this viewpoint is not shared by all. Still. many people do believe that more information enhances decision making. even if it doesn't explicitly point to decisions. Schmid (1978) points out that no matter how good the information is on costs and benefits. there is still no objective decision rule for choosing winners and losers in regulatory decisions. The concept of potential Pareto- optimality in neoclassical welfare economics is based on an assumption that winners reimburse losers: however. this does not occur in the real world. Schmid feels that a careful 24This conclusion is reached after adopting the norma- tive premises that utility can be summed across individuals and that objective values can be obtained for benefits and costs. -53- taxonomy and analysis of impacts can lead to better-informed decisions. and therefore is very useful. but such informa- tion does not tell regulators what to decide. Lowrance (1976) specifically' addresses. risk..analysis. such as the type used in pesticide regulation. He disting- uishes between two subprocesses in regulatory risk analyses: the determination of risk. which has the potential of being a scientific process. and the judgment of the acceptability of that risk. which is a value judgment. Like Schmid. he feels that information can provide the regulator with a determination of policy impacts. but it does not provide an answer as to the acceptability of those impacts. Majone (1979) also feels that risk evaluation is not scientific or factual due to uncertainty and the necessity of value judgments in regulatory decisions. He believes that changes in the decision process may result in the channeling of disagreement and conflict into better infor- mation and better decisions. Characteristics of Information Search. Several authors stress the need for regulators to make uncertainty and information overload more manageable in decision making. ALl of these authors suggest that decision makers develop standard operating procedures to achieve this manageability. van Ravenswaay and Hull (1981) look at the information requirements of food safety regulation which would result if the goal of a regulator was maximization of net social bene— fits. They imply that there is a market for information. _54- with supply determined by costs of the information and demand determined in part by the agency's information budget. Both information costs and the information budget are affected by the regulatory context (including methods for calculating the maximum amount of a contaminant to allow in food. legal and technical constraints on information production. and the total budget and other tasks facing the agency) and by characteristics of the regulatory problem (including complexity. familiarity and urgency).25 Since the agency is unable to "buy" perfect knowledge. strategies are developed to deal with uncertainty and conflict. Strat- egies for obtaining information on risks from food contami- nants include using high-dosage animal tests to determine toxicity. extrapolating results from animals to humans and from high-dose to low-dose. and making assumptions about human exposure. Strategies for dealing with benefits in- clude assuming full compliance and ignoring changes in the price of food (and of other inputs in the production of food) due to impacts of the proposed regulation. Thus. reg- ulators simplify their information search in order to make it more manageable. Fiorino and Metlay (1977) also hypothesize that agency strategies for coping with uncertainty are a crucial aspect of decision making. When uncertainty is present in a prob- lem. standard Operating procedures for dividing issues into 25Many of these variables are controlled by interested parties. including the regulated firms and Congress. -55- sets of simpler problems are developed. These strategies tend to be cybernetic. with previous outcomes partially determining current strategies. Sometimes these strategies fail to ensure rational decision making under uncertainty: major issues may not be noticed. the decision process may not be sensitized to signs of failure. subjective judgments may have unintended outcomes. there may be imprecision in implementing desired solutions and standard operating proce- dures may not be useful when a case-by-case approach is needed. Edmunds (1980) also stresses the need for agencies to simplify problems to make them more manageable. He specif- ically' addresses the complexity and information overload which accompany environmental policy decisions. One way in which information is reduced to manageable levels is by excluding consideration of some of the impacts of environ- mental activity. or by ”bounding the problem rationally.” Thus. complex interrelationships are reduced to simpler concepts which are comprehensible to humans. Furthermore. regulatory agencies and decision making processes are actually structured to deal with issues within the bounded area of a problem. and to ignore issues outside of that domain. Information search goes no further than the or- ganization's boundaries. In the case of toxic substances. where uncertainty is present in both problem definition and solution. EPA definitely must limit the amount of informa- tion obtained on interactions between chemicals and the —56- ecological and economic systems. Congress has helped the agency to some extent in this bounding process. Sabatier (1978) provides a framework to conceptualize the acquisition and provision of technical information in regulatory decision making. He is essentially describing an information market. Provision of information depends on resources. characteristics of the problem. the legal and political setting. and the expected reaction of decision makers to the information. Acquisition of information varies between agencies. within an agency. and between branches of government. Between branches of government. acquisition is affected by agency resources relative to other branches. sources of legitimization of decisions. agency mandates and court review of agency decisions. Dif— ferences in acquisition Of information within an agency can be explained by the degree of risk from decision impacts. the social class of affected groups. the degree of conflict and the potential influence of the information on decisions. Variance between agencies depends on personnel. the degree of risk from decision impacts. the capacity and willingness of agencies to deal with technical issues and the amount Of conflict in the political environment.26 Sabatier shows that information search can be limited by many factors other than the complexity of the problem. 261n the presence of conflict. agencies may seek in- formation. on political preferences rather than technical information. -57- In summary. the authors in this section suggest that information acquisition is not simply a matter of deter- mining what data are needed and then obtaining them. Information costs. complexity of the problem. and political. legal. budgetary. technical and time constraints are just a few of the factors which determine the search for and ac- quisition of information. The Use of Information. After information is acquired. how do agencies use it in the decision making process? The literature addressing this question is categorized according to the way it answers the question. Information leads to rational decisions. Neoclass- ical welfare economics deserves mention under this category. It is widely believed among economists that policy analysis involves obtaining information on net benefits of alterna- tive policies. and that once enough information is acquired the only remaining task is to determine which policy alter- 27 This view assumes native maximizes net social benefits. that the goal of regulator is (or ought to be) to maximize net social benefits. an assumption which has been discred- ited by the theories of regulatory decision making presented earlier in this chapter. Information is used by conflicting interests to influence decision makers. Several authors believe that 27Accordingly. much criticism from these economists centers on the failure of regulators to Obtain the ”correct” information and choose the most efficient solution. ~58- analysis is used by interested parties to influence decision making. Johnson (1973) feels that information contained in economic analysis is not used as much as information from interested parties in making decisions. According to Johnson. the Federal Communications Commission (and assumed— 1y. other regulatory bodies) sees itself as a quasi—judicial body which gathers information from interested parties and then makes decisions based on that information rather than on formal economic analysis. Randall Bartlett (1973) prOposes that uncertainty in decision making results in information subsidies to agencies from interest groups and individuals who control access to information. Shaffer (1979) also feels that parties who control information are able to influence regulatory deci- sion making. since they provide information on preferences of various groups. Stigler and Peltzman both acknowledge the potential use of information to influence decision mak- ing by including lobbying and the mitigation of opposition to a policy as variables in their theories. Information legitimizes decisions. ‘The idea that information serves to legitimize previously-made agency decisions is accepted by several theorists. Majone (1979). in trying to persuade analysts to examine the process by which decisions are made rather than the outcomes. sees analysis as a legitimization of decisions: -59- ”Regulators have sought legitimacy for their decisions by wrapping them in a cloak of scientific respectability."28 Kelman (1974) also thinks that information justifies. rather than aids. decision making when he studies the risk- based regulatory process of the Consumer Safety Product Commission (CSPC). Regulators must make a velue judgment regarding safety (see Lowrance (1976)). One of the apparent biases in CSPC is to at least partially decrease risk when a product is investigated. In order to cope with uncertainty. the CPSC has devel- oped an information system to obtain data on injuries from products and accompanying decision rules to determine which products to regulate. Kelman suggests that the CPSC puts energy and resources into the justification of product investigation. the determination of the expected success of the chosen policy (as Opposed to all alternative policies) and estimates of the worth of averted risks and the costs associated with the chosen policy. Finally. Andrews (1980) suggests that information is Obtained and documented in order to satisfy superiors within an agency (or external reviewers. such as the Congress) and to support previously-made decisions. Complex regulatory decisions are too value-laden to be solved by information alone. Andrews takes this idea a step further by hypothe- sizing that information may actually result in worse 28Majone. p. 561. -60- decisions by confusing affected parties and diverting attention from crucial issues. Information (clarifies issues and Jpotential solu- tiggg. Another widely—held impression is; that information aids the decision maker in determining what the issues in a regulatory problem are. and what the potential solutions to the problem are. Schwerin and Coyer (1979). like many other theorists. recognize that regulatory decisions must be political choices. but they attempt to show that the state of knowl- edge and/or the amount of information in a particular policy area affects the amounts of uncertainty and disagreement in decision making. which in turn determine the outcomes of decision rules based on voting. bargaining or hierarchy. Knowledge is "paradigmatic" when there is a generally accepted way of analyzing the problem and "preparadigmatic" when there is no clear theoretical basis for analyzing the problem. Schwerin and Coyer hypothesize that. given the amount of information. paradigmatic knowledge narrows the range of alternative solutions available to decision makers since there is less uncertainty as to what the issues are and how they can be solved. Decision outcomes are also predicted based on the state of the knowledge. decision- making rules and the power structure involved. Maynard—Moody and McClintock (1981) feel that applied policy research plays a large role in helping decision makers grasp issues and limit possible solutions. Policy -6l- analysis provides general background information for prob- lems rather than specific answers. Multiple uses of information. Many authors acknowledge various uses of policy research without placing special emphasis on any particular use. They generally agree with the preceding authors on the nature of the uses of information. Paul Sabatier (1978) provides a framework for informa- tion use along with the previously described framework on information acquisition and provision. In this framework. information is used to influence decision makers: to conform with mandates. case law. ethics. standard operating proce- dures and court review (i.e.. to justify decisions): and to facilitate long-term changes in agency perspective. There are many determinants Of how information is used in Sabatier's framework -- some include the resources of the information source (credibility. communication. skills. power). the content of the information message. the political context and the resources and perspective Of decision makers. An implication is that the greater the degree of conflict in a regulatory issue the more informa- tion is obtained (all other variables equal). but the less influence it has on decision making. A work similar in scope to Sabatier's is the article by Peter H. Schuck (1979). Schuck outlines five general groups of factors which may affect the implementation of a regula- tory program. Information is only one of the five groups. —62- implyimg that many other factors may determine decisions. Those other factors include the structure of the regulated parties. the nature of the regulatory Objective. the en- forceability of the regulation and the political support for the regulation. Although Schuck does not specifically predict the impact on regulation of the fifth group Of factors. supply of and demand for information. the implica- tion is that information use in regulatory decision making depends on the other groups of factors as well as on the sources and availability of information. the quality of information. the quantity of information and other deter- minants Of information supply and demand. Finally. Park (1973) suggests several alternative uses of information when he concludes that policy analysis does not point to a clear decision. Information may be used by conflicting interests to support their viewpoints. it may be used by the agency and its supporters to justify previously- made decisions. or it may provide regulators with a common framework for discussing the policy issues of specific problems. Summary: The Nature and Use of Information in Regula- tory Decision Making. ‘The above theorists all agree that there is much more to regulatory decision making than ob- taining objective information to make economically efficient decisions. Regulators have discretion in decision making: thus. decision making is influenced by factors such as the -63- goals of the agency and the power of other groups to influ- ence the agency. Information may be used to justify deci— sions. influence decision makers or clarify issues and potential solutions. and this use is also affected by a variety' those impacts which are transfers of income. wealth or util- ity between individuals or groups rather than net societal increases or decreases in income. wealth or utility. Exam— ples of pecuniary impacts that may result from pesticide use include: 1. Decreases in output prices to producers who don't use the pesticide and to producers of substitute products. offset by savings to consumers. 2. Impacts on input markets (e.g.. changes in relative prices) other than transfer costs. offset by impacts on buyers of inputs. 3. Impacts on markets for insurance and health care due to more or less illness. offset by impacts on consumers of those services. Other examples of pecuniary impacts could be found. depending on the specific pesticide and its circumstances Of use. Distribution of impacts. The benefits and risks of pesticide use are distributed among many participants in and -86- out of the marketplace. Voluntary risk (e.g.. risk to pest- icide applicators) may be better known to the risk-bearer. and thus may be borne in part by the risk-imposer in finan— cial terms and by the risk-bearer in health and financial terms. 'If risk is involuntary and unknown. then the risk— bearers will probably be faced with all of the risk. Risk distributed among the risk-bearers may also be partly passed on to employers in the form of lower productivity. and to families and friends in the form of suffering. reduced longevity. etc. Real net benefits are also distributed among various parties. The changes in value of production and production costs are enjoyed by producers who use the pesticide. pro- ducers who don't use the pesticide (who actually may suffer a decline in income if product prices fall) and consumers of the product. Improved safety and nutrition are enjoyed by the general public and are evidenced by improved health and productivity. although health care industries may experience reduced revenues. The avoidance of capital losses and transfer costs is of benefit to the owners of inputs and users of inputs. and probably consumers Of the final product of those inputs. Taxpayers and regulated firms profit from the avoidance of regulatory costs. When the costs of re- lated production processes increase due to pesticide toxicity. producers and consumers of those goods generally bear those costs. Finally. environmentalists and related groups suffer from environmental impacts of pesticide use. -87- The distribution of pecuniary impacts depends on the impact in question. As already mentioned. competitive market producers who don't use a pesticide benefit if the price of the product increases and pay if it falls (at least in terms of returns per unit). This is a pecuniary impact. ans it is offset by prices paid by consumers. These same effects hold true for producers of substitutes for the final product. Producers Of complementary products Observe the opposite impacts: they benefit if the product price falls and pay if it increases. Market prices for other products. such as insurance and health care. may be affected by pest- icide use and are distributed among the producers and the consumers of the product. Non-transfer cost impacts on owners of inputs. such as changes in relative and/or abso- lute prices of inputs. are offset by impacts on input buyers and ultimately on consumers of the product for which the inputs are used. Other pecuniary impacts are distributed similarly. Impacts may be distributed disproportionately on a geographic basis. as well as among groups. Individuals in a particular region of the country may use more of a pest- icide. consume greater amounts of pesticide residue. or own resources with less mobility. In addition. if pesticide use has macroeconomic implications. other individuals may be affected in different ways than outlined above. It is conceivable that the use of pesticides could have such a profound effect (Hi the production of unufli of the nation's -88- supply of a given commodity that employment. price levels. balance of payments. and other macroeconomic variables would change. Finally. the relationship of the economic system to political and social variables may result in societal changes. PROBLEMS IN MEASURING IMPACTS A conceptualization Of the impacts of pesticide use was accomplished in the previous discussion and is summarized in Figure 3.6. The first section of this chapter pointed out some of the many difficulties in conceptualizing impacts. There are additional problems involved in measuring impacts once they have been conceptualized. Risk is difficult to measure due to a lack of informa- tion on the response of humans to various doses and on human exposure to the pesticide. Extrapolation from high dose to low dose. from nonhumans to humans. and from a test system to actual environmental conditions is necessary in order to estimate risk. In addition. some method of estimating human exposure must be devised. In some instances. technology is not available for accurate measurement: in other cases. accurate measurement is too costly to perform. The result is that EPA either omits the information on risk from the regulatory decision or implements lower cost and technolog- ically feasible strategies for developing dose response and exposure data. These strategies are discussed in Chapter 5. I. Risks A. B. C. D. -89- Exposure to affected groups via various routes. Toxicity of chemical. Risk analysis. Distribution among risk bearers. risk imposers. others. II. Net Benefits A. Real 1. Value of increased output of product. 2. Value of increased quality of output. 3. Decreases in costs of production of original output. 4. Costs of producing new output. 5. Improved health and safety resulting from better nutrition. fewer automobile accidents. etc. 6. Avoidance of: Capital losses to users of in- puts. unemployment. or other costs of trans- ferring resources. 7. Avoidance of costs of regulating pesticide. 8. Increases in costs of related production processes. 9. Environmental impacts other than risk and production process impacts. Pecuniary 1. Changes in output prices to non—using pro- ducers. 2. Impacts on input markets. 3. Other. Distribution of Benefits hWNH 0 Among groups. Geographic. Macroeconomic benefits. Social/Political benefits. Figure 3.6 - Summary of Conceptualization of Benefits and Risks -90- 'The measurement Of net real benefits can also present problems for regulators. At best. information on changes in ////”” yield due to pesticide use are Obtained from agricultural test plots. These sample plots may not coincide with actual environmental conditions in which crops are grown. It also may be difficult to obtain pesticide price and use data. im— pacts Of quantity changes on product price. impacts of pest- t/“ icide use (N1 other inputs 1J1 the production process. etc. Net real benefits not accounted for in market prices are even more difficult to quantify. as are net real benefits accruing to groups other than the users of the pesticide and pecuniary impacts. The problem in measuring net benefits is considered by most economists to be one of costs rather than one of technology. As a result of limited budgets. EPA must again develop strategies for incorporating information on net real benefits in risk-benefit analyses. Some of these strategies are presented in Chapter 5. Finally. distributions of impacts are difficult and costly to measure. Determining who gets what share of real and pecuniary impacts demands a knowledge of the general equilibrium nature of the economic system -- knowledge which is complex and expensive. CHAPTER 4 METHODOLOGY INTRODUCTION The next step in the research. after examining theoreti- cal literature on regulatory decision making and the risks and benefits of pesticide use. was to attempt to empirically describe the quality of information obtained by the EPA and to use measures of some of the variables suggested by the regulatory decision making literature to explain the quality of information. This chapter describes the choice of a data base. the measurement Of explanatory variables. the measure- ment of dependent variables. and the measurement of correla— tion between the explanatory and dependent variables. CHOICE OF DATA BASE The decision was made to use case studies as the source Of data on explanatory and dependent variables. It was felt that case studies would best describe the quality of infor- mation used by EPA in pesticide decision making. Using case studies from the same agency and governed by the same stat- ute most likely eliminated some of the variation between cases. thus providing more certainty in the empirical re— sults. Lave. in The Strategy pf Social Regulation. conducts an analysis of regulatory processes with case studies. In -91- -92- the words of Crandall and Lave. "It is ironic that the evidence for the enhanced role of scientific data and analysis is a set of case studies ~- soft. impressionistic material ~- which is being used to suggest the value of hard analysis! But we know of no better way to illuminate the role of scientific evidence in the world of regula- tion.”31 The cases chosen for study were the eight pesticides for which the RPAR process had been completed when the empirical work began in March of 1982: Chlorobenzilate. DBCP. Prona- mide. Amitraz. 2.4.5-T. Silvex. Endrin and Dimethoate.32 There was also some discretion as to where to obtain the data for each case pesticide. The decision was to use the sets of printed public position documents generated as an output of the RPAR process. There is justification for the use of so-called "paper trails" in previous research. 33 explain that different types Maynard-Moody and McClintock of research should be used when analyzing different regula- tory processes. They cite two variables. ”outcome standards“ and "causal understanding." that should be used to evaluate a regulatory process to determine how to conduct research of that process. In organizations theory. outcome standards refer to agency goals and causal understanding 31Lester Lave. The Strategy of Social Regulation (Washing- ton. D.C.: The Brookings Institution. 1981). p. 16. 32Since that time. 10 additional RPARs have been completed. 33Maynard-Moody and McClintock. pp. 644-666. -93- refers to the relationships between agency actions and results. If both are ambiguous. as one could definitely argue in the EPA's regulation of pesticides. then re— searchers need a methodology that does not assume rigid agency goals. The authors' suggestions? Case studies. among other things. and qualitative measurement that relies on observations. paper trails. and enabling legislation. “Where quantitative measurement is used.“ they write on page 651. ”its purpose is to illuminate patterns of behavior in the program.” The authors acknowledge that 'By relying solely on reports. judgments about the evaluations were based only on written comments. and there may be differences between what actually happened and what was reported. It is possible that insights and problems that were important ... were not described. Nevertheless published reports are an accessible source of information that reflect. however imperfectly. the issues discussed.” The authors' main point is that carefully designed studies of the "efficiency” of a regulatory process are not relevant when it is not even clear what the agency goals are. Many other researchers have used paper trails in studies of agency decisions. The studies are Often descriptive in nature: the researchers generally’ acknowledge that paper trails may constitute an incomplete picture of the regula— tory process. but it is felt that the documents could improve understanding of the process. -94- The position documents describe information sources and measures of explanatory variables in a relatively consistent manner between pesticides (as well as between uses of a single pesticide). which made them ideal for comparison. They are also interesting from the standpoint of analyzing EPA's public record. There is justification for using other sources of data. especially interviews with EPA officials and/or interest group representatives. Such interviews would have reflected participants' perceptions of the quality of EPA's informa- tion (which might not have always been accurate). as well as allowing the researcher to obtain more details on the EPA's data sources. However. time and financial constraints did not allow the exercise of this option. MEASURING EXPLANATORY VARIABLES Which Variables? The literature on regulatory decision making described in Chapter 2 pointed to a variety of vari- ables that might explain decision making. It was decided to investigate the explanatory power of variables reflecting the incentives and power of different interest groups over the information-gathering portion of the idecision making process. Three major groups stand out as having a stake in pesti- cide decision outcomes: pesticide manufacturers. pesticide -95- users. and risk-bearers. The principles of the Peltzman— type theories suggest that pesticide manufacturers might be able to influence the regulatory process because the major manufacturers are relatively few in number (thus reducing organization costs) and in many cases the stakes appear to be rather high due to the sale of large quantities of a pesticide by individual corporations. Pesticide users are usually more dispersed in terms of numbers and distribution of impacts. although there are incidents of oligopoly (such as strawberry nursery stock growers in Delaware and Maryland. and pineapple growers in Hawaii). Risk-bearers are likely to be even more dispersed. There is no formal organization to express the views of the millions of people consuming food with pesticide residues: there is not even a vocal organization for workers exposed to harmful pesticides. Furthermore. the risks are not at all well known to exposed sectors of the population and it is not apparent what they could do if they decided that the risk of being exposed exceeded the benefits. To reflect the power of these interest groups over the decision making process. the following explanatory variables were chosen. 1) The stake of pesticide manufacturers in the outcome of the regulatory process. measured by the product of the retail price per unit of the pesticide and the units of pesticide used for a particular crop. 2) 3) -96- Thus. the researcher attempted to measure this variable for each use of each pesticide (86 uses in all). This measure was intended to proxy the relative value of different uses of a pesticide tc> the manufacturer. It is hypothesized that greater' value of a pesticide use to manufacturers leads tc> more and better information on that use. The stake of pesticide users (producers) in the outcome of the regulatory process. measured two ways: by the annual per acre user losses from pesticide cancellation for each use and by the annual total user losses from pesticide cancella— tion for each use. Again. this variable was measured for as many of the 86 uses as possible. It is hypothesized that a greater economic stake to producers leads to more and better information. The percentage of total acres of a crop treated with the pesticide was also used as a measure of an explanatory variable. The measure was intended to proxy the number of users affected for each pesti- cide use. Stigler and Peltzman hypothesized that the more users. the greater the difficulty in organizing the political interest group. But growers often have already-organized user groups. including the USDA. to represent them in the political process. Therefore. the hypothesis 4) -97- tested was that a larger percentage of the partic- ular crop or use would result in better information because it would serve as a larger incentive for' user groups to become involved. This hypothesis is not necessarily restricted to information on bene—- fits. A similar argument can be made for risk information. since widespread use may spring risk— bearers' groups into action. In addition. risk- bearers may react to better information from users with increased information of their own. The amount of risk is hypothesized to be positively related to the quality of information. However. this hypothesis is very difficult to measure for a particular use of a pesticide. or even between uses of a pesticide. because risk is usually constant per unit of exposure for a pesticide. and data on exposure and number of exposed persons are poor. Instead. the decision was made to use risk tO predict the quality of information between the different_pesticides. So. unlike the other ex- planatory variables. this variable was measured for each of the 8 pesticides rather than for each of the 86 uses. EPA's own ranking of the RPAR pesti- cides was used to measure risk. particularly in light of the following comment by Edwin Johnson. Director of EPA's Office of Pesticide Programs: -98- "Pesticide law requires that both risks and benefits be considered in all deci- sions. But risk drives the process in terms of depth of analysis and allocation of agency resources. The greater the apparent or potential for risk. the more in-depth the analysis of both risks and benefits. the more resources devoted to the evaluation. and the greater the de- gree of public involvement and scrutiny accorded the decision.“ (Emphasis added).34 So according to the people who make the decisions. more and better information is gathered for pesti- cides with greater actual or perceived risk. 13: addition. the public (interest groups?) becomes more involved when there is a higher degree of actual or perceived risk. How Measured? As mentioned previously. the EPA's pub- lished position documents served as the data base for the eight case study pesticides. The data for the explanatory variables did not always just ”fall out" of the position documents. Rather. measures for the variables often had to be calculated. 34Edwin L. Johnson. ”Risk Assessment in an Administrative Agency.“ The American Statistician 36. rum. 3. part 2 (August 1982): p. 233. -99- Value of pesticide use to manufacturers. The measure used to proxy the value of a pesticide use to the manufacturer was the quantity of pesticide used times the pesticide's retail price per Ludln This measure was used purely for ranking the pesticide uses: it was assumed that the ratio of wholesale price to retail price is relatively constant between uses of a pesticide and that manufacturer costs per unit Of the pesticide are constant for all uses. If these assumptions are correct. then the data provides an accurate picture of the relative economic importance of the different uses of the pesticide to manufacturers. The time period chosen for measuring the quantity of pesticide used was one year. This caused some problems in the case of DBCP. because this nematocide is often applied on a three-year cycle. For those uses. the quantity was determined as the one-year average. In addition. amounts of pesticide used were sometimes described as "minor." "little." or "negligible." In such instances. the pesticide use was assigned an annual value to manufacturer of 100. which placed that use below the uses for which the values were calculated. Position documents 2/3 and supplementary benefits analyses were the sources of this data. Retail prices for the pesticides were fairly easily found in the position documents 2/3. Occasionally. dif- ferent forms of the pesticide were used for different uses. so there was more than one price for the pesticide. -100- Table 4.1 shows the value of uses of DBCP to manufactur- ers. as an example. Data for the other pesticides can be found in Appendix A. Value of pesticide use to producers. Two measures were used to describe the economic stake of producers in uses of a pesticide: annual total user losses of pesticide cancellation and annual per acre user losses of pesticide cancellation. Again. data for both measures were obtained from the position documents (primarily PD 2/3s). Pesticide uses with qualitative descriptions such as ”minor.” “negli- gible.“ “little." ”insignificant.” or 'small' were assigned a value of 100 for total costs and .25 for per acre costs. placing them in a lower ranking than those uses for which costs to producers could be calculated. Table 4.1 Value to Manufacturers of Uses of DBCP Price of DBCP Pounds used Value to 233 per pound ($) Annually Manufacturer Soybeans .67 12.378.000 8.293.260 Grapes 1.00 3.200.000 3.200.000 Almonds .67 3.417.000 2.289.390 Vegetables/Melons/ Strawberries .66 3.392.000 2.238.720 Peanuts .67 3.195.000 2.140.650 Cotton .66 2.700.000 1.782.000 Peaches/Nectarines .66 1.823.000 1.203.180 Citrus .62 112921000 8011040 Commercial Turf .66 550.000 363.000 Plums .67 452.000 302.840 Pineapple .83 302.000 250.660 Home Lawns .67 200.000 134.000 Other Berries .67 92.000 61.640 Strawberry Nursery Stock .67 16.000 10.720 Home Gardens .67 5.000 3.350 Bananas - negligible 100 Apricots/Cherries/Figs - negligible 100 Ornamentals — unknown ? -101- The total losses measure was intended to depict the industry—wide net economic impact Of pesticide cancellation. whereas per acre losses provided information on the approx- imate net impact of cancellation per producer. The former‘ measure. if correlated with the quality Of information. would lend credence to the hypothesis that producer groups provide information according to total dollars at stake. The latter measure would go along with Peltzman and Stigler's hypothesis that per capita economic stake helps drive the political process. The original intent was to report costs of cancellation per average-sized farm for each use of each pesticide. but such data were simply not avail— able. so the per acre cost figures had to be used instead. Again. the problem: of' multi-year' application cycles. namely for DBCP. had to be solved. Annual averages were calculated when losses from pesticide cancellation were reported for multiple-year cycles. Data were not always available for per acre user losses from pesticide cancellation because there were not always data on acres treated with the pesticide. When there were no quantitative or qualitative data. the use was not in— cluded in the analysis of correlation between per acre costs and quality of information. Table 4.2 and 4.3 show annual total and per acre costs of cancellation of DBCP. respec- tively. Data for other pesticides can be found in Appendix A. -102- Table 4.2 Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation for DBCP (Annual) Use Peaches/Nectarines Soybeans Grapes Vegetables/Melons/Strawberries Citrus Almonds Peanuts Pineapple Commercial Turf Strawberry Nursery Stock Plums Home Lawns Cotton Other Berries Apricots. Figs. Cherries. Walnuts Bananas Home Gardens Ornamentals * per year. after three years. ** annual averages based on three-year Total Annual Costs (5) $ 26.890.000** 23.500.000 21.670.000** 14.500.000 8.950.000** 8.834.000** 6.800.000 6.200.000* 2.200.000-5.600.000 l.500.000-5.600.000 4.600.000** 2.750.000 2.600.000 1.000.000 "negligible” (100) ”negligible" (100) "negligible" (100) 9 crop cycles. -103- Table 4.3 Annual Per Acre and Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation for DBCP Annual Per Acre Total Acres Costs of £33 Costs (S) Treated Cancellation ($) Strawberry Nursery $1.500.000 $2.500.00 Stock to to 5.600.000 600 9.333.00* Pineapple 6.200.000 5.000 l.240.00* Peaches/Nectarines 26.890.000 42.000 640.24* Plums 4.600.000 9.000 511.00* Commercial Turf 2.200.000 118.92 to to 5.600.000 18.500 302.70* Citrus 8.950.000 31.200 286.86* Grapes 21.670.000 83.000 261.08* Ornamentals ? ? 88.08 to 172.55 Almonds 8.834.000 71.000 124.42* Home Lawns 2.750.000 31.250 88.00* Vegetables/Melons/ Strawberries 14.500.000 374.000 38.77* Soybeans 23.500.000 1.133.000 20.74 Peanuts 6.800.000 355.000 19.15* Cotton 2.600.000 225.000 11.56* Other Berries 1.000.000 600 .25 Home Gardens ”negligible” ? .25 Apricots/Figs/ Cherries/Walnuts "negligible“ ”negligible” .25 Bananas “negligible” ”negligible" .25 * Calculated by author ~104- Percentage of producers affected. As previously mentioned. it was hypothesized that a higher percentage of affected producers would serve as an incentive for producer groups to involve themselves in the regulatory process. The best measure of percentage of producers affected was the percentage of total acres in the nation treated with the pesticide. The assumption was that the percentage of acres treated was directly related to the number of producers who use the pesticide. If the percentage of acres treated was described as ”very minor“ or ”little.” a value of .01% of total acres treated was assigned to the use of the pesticide. which ranked the use below those uses for which quantitative estimates had been obtained. In the case of endrin. the percentage of acres treated for ”other vegetable seeds" was described as "like water- melon and conifers.” The percentage for watermelon and conifer seeds was 100% and 90% respectively. so a value of 90% was assigned to other vegetable seeds. If there were no qualitative or quantitative data on the percentage of acres treated. the use was not included in the data base. If crOp cycles exceeded or were less than one year. the percent of the crop treated per cycle was used. Table 4.4 shows the percentage Of acres treated. intended to proxy the percentage of affected producers. for DCBP. Data for other pesticides can be found in Appendix A. -105- Table 4.4 Percentage of Acres Treated with DBCP (Per Crop Cycle) Use Percent of Crop Treated Strawberry Nursery Stock 100% Vegetables/Melons/Strawberries 8.1% to 95% Plums 70% Almonds 54% Pineapple 46% Peaches/Nectarines 44% Grapes 31% Peanuts 23% Citrus 7.9% Soybeans 2.1% Cotton 2.0% Home Gardens <0.5% Other Berries <0.1% Apricots/Cherries/Figs/Walnuts <0.l% Bananas 9 UOOMHsonO mm3 :OHSB .NmuuHsd mow bewoxm- ehmH ..O.o .COumchan [Hm-Es: men-9800.5 Lemmas: Dow-Home: .msz>wm mpHoHumwm 130QO no 03qu .<.m.m.m.D "wousom .meu mwumwum wumoHch mmmoom Hmuou no“ Ucm mHumuHuu Hm5©H>H©cH co nmuoum Lou enemas: mmcmHm« e s n 5 NH MH MH Hm mmoom qcm o o O o m o m w coHumHsEsoomon Ucm coHumoHuHcmmEOHm H o m m m H N v mocwuanmme -h o o o o H m H m OMHHGHHZ m can anm 0» >3on8. - o m o o H m H m nHmEEmz Ou wuHOone wusu< o o H H o o o o mHmssmz 0» quxoe OHcOLLO uwcuo v v o o v v v v 388.3808 0 o m m o m H N coHuuseoum Hmuoa weHcmEoum NmuuHE< alm.w.m xw>HHm wumocquHo some wumHHNcmb cHuecm mHmwuHuU IouoHcU wuoom «mUHOHunwm comm uOm mmoum mam mem mcHEumuwo Cu new: mHmwuflHu umcchmm mem meHOHumOm n.¢mm ©.v wHQmH ~108- Problems in measurigg explanatory variables. There were some problems in measuring the explanatory variables. Specifically. the "value to manufacturers" variable was proxied by using retail price times the quantity Of the pes- ticide used annually. Within a pesticide. this measure presumed a constant relationship between wholesale and retail prices and a constant rate of return between uses of the pesticide. For comparison between pesticides. it pre- sumed a constant rate of return. For "annual total user losses from pesticide cancella— tion." data were often available for crop or application cycles rather than on an annual basis. In those instances. averages were calculated to reflect annual values. Averages may not have reflected the loss picture in a particular year. but they did provide a basis for overall comparison between uses of a pesticide. For one pesticide. there was difficulty in calculating ”annual per acre user losses." These data had generally been calculated by EPA. but in the case of DBCP. they had to be calculated by the researcher. This was accomplished by dividing ”annual total user losses" by the estimated number of acres treated. In the case of "percent of acres treated." the data were fairly attainable for crop or application cycles. There was no need to calculate the average annual percentage of acres treated. since the intent was to capture the proportion of producers affected in general rather than the proportion affected in a single year. -109- The EPA's risk ranking for the pesticides was considered to be relatively reliable. It reflects EPA's own perception of risk. which is most relevant since it was being used to test Johnson's hypothesis that more risk led to more and better information. The calculation of relative risk for' Amitraz was not difficult. although the researcher was not completely sure of the values for biomagnification/ bioaccumulation and persistence. based on the information in the position documents. Phone calls to EPA indicated that Amitraz never had been ranked according to risk. In general. there was a problem in measuring the ex- planatory variables with data from EPA's own risk benefit analyses. If EPA assigned qualitative or low values in- accurately. simply because there was no information. there may have been a bias introduced into the empirical work. For example. EPA may have described annual total costs of DBCP cancellation to banana producers as being “negligible“ because there was no information rather than because there was information that DBCP use on bananas really was negli- gible. However. EPA often made a distinction between an unknown value and a negligible value for explanatory vari- ables. MEASURING DEPENDENT VARIABLES Which Measured? The dependent variables in this re- search refer to the quality of information obtained by EPA to describe the various impacts of pesticide use. Chapter 3 was devoted to a description of the potential risks and -llO- benefits of pesticide use: this conceptualization was the basis for delineating and organizing the impacts which EPA calculated and could have calculated. EPA's consistency in measuring impacts across pesticides helped the researcher break the impacts apart into variables for which the EPA collected data. It was the quality of information obtained for these variables which served as the dependent variables. EPA's consistency was also important for the one explanatory variable (EPA's risk ranking) used to compare the quality of information between pesticides rather than between uses. Tables 4.7 and 4.8 describe typical sets of variables per- taining to risk and benefits for a pesticide. The goals in designing these sets were tO cover the impacts that EPA measured. to make them broad enough to allow for comparisons between pesticides. and to make them specific enough to describe variation between uses of a pesticide. These tables can serve as a comparison with Figure 3.5. which outlines the theoretical conceptualization of benefits and risks. In general. EPA spent virtually all of its resources measuring what most people would consider to be the major impacts -- risk analyses for the major groups (applicators and consumers. in particular). the benefits from increased value (HE production. and the benefits from reduced (or increased) pest control costs. Most of the- pecuniary and distributional impacts were ignored for the eight pesticides. and some of the risk categories (espe— cially farmworkers and exposure to spills and drift) also -111- Table 4.7 Typical Risk Variables for Which Quality of Information was Measured Toxicity Exposure. Human Consumers Residues in food Amount of food in diet Percent Of crOp treated Risk Ground Applicators Dermal Amount of pesticide exposure Absorption of pesticide through skin Duration of exposure Inhalation Amount of pesticide exposure Absorption of pesticide Duration of exposure Dietary Residues in food Amount of food in diet Percent of crop treated Risk Oncogenicity Fetotoxicity/Reproductive Effects Mutagenicity Aerial Applicators. Mixers and Loaders. Farmworkers. Persons exposed via drift. Persons exposed via spills. Flaggers Same as for Ground Applicators Exposure. Wildlife Decreases in Nontarget Species Potential exposure Lethal dose required to kill 50% of test animals (L050) Likelihood of exposure Risk Acute Toxicity to Wildlife Residues in food LD50 Amount of food consumed Risk Fatality to Endangered Species Exposure LD50 Risk -112— Table 4.8 Benefits Variables for Which Quality of Information was Measured Changes in pest control costs due to pesticide cancellation Cost of pesticide per unit Amount of pesticide used per acre Acres treated with pesticide Cost of alternative pest control per unit Amount of alternative used per acre Acres that would be treated with alternative Acres that would be abandoned Per acre changes in pest control costs Total changes in pest control costs Changes in yield due to pesticide cancellation Yield per acre with pesticide Yield per acre with alternative pest control Quality of product per acre with pesticide Quality of product per acre with alternative pest control Price per unit of product Per acre change in value of production Total change in value of production Changes in other production costs Impacts on producers of other goods Distribution of impacts Users Of pesticide Nonusers Marketers of product Consumers of product Pesticide manufacturers Geographic distribution of impacts Macroeconomic impacts Social impacts Probability of compliance with EPA restrictions Cost of restrictions to users -ll3- were ignored for virtualLy all of the pesticides. In ad- dition. the dietary exposure route was usually ignored for the non-consumer risk categories. In summary. EPA never met the standard set forth in Chapter 3 for measuring the impacts of pesticide use -- many Of the impacts were ignored or. at best. qualitatively discussed (mentioned might be a better word). How then. was the transition made from a theoretical conceptualization of impacts to a pragmatic description in Tables 4.6 and 4.7 of which "bits" EPA actually looked at 1J1 its position docu- ments? Mainly. the transition was made by carefully reading and rereading the position documents. Detailed study of the documents in chronological order (according to the date of publication Of the PD 2/3s) revealed an incremental approach by EPA in determining which impacts of the different pesti- cide uses to measure. how to measure them. and sources of data. How Measured? By far. the largest block Of time in the empirical work was spent measuring the dependent variables (i.e.. the quality of information for the variables which made up the impacts of pesticide use). Position documents were painstakingly read and reread to obtain first a broad picture of the impacts for each pesticide use and how they were measured and then a detailed picture of how the impacts were measured. -ll4- Impacts were initially listed on separate sheets of paper. with details on how each impact was measured by EPA. Based on this information. and after impacts were outlined. measurement scales were developed for each impact. These scales are depicted in Tables 4.9 to 4.19. The measurement scales were then applied to each impact for each use of each pesticide. The data were obtained by once more carefully reading the PD 2/3s and benefits analyses. and were coded by hand onto large sheets of paper. On the first reading. data were coded only for those impacts for which the quality of information (i.e.. the information source) was fairly-well documented. This comprised approximately 2/3 of the data. The documents were scoured again to obtain data on the less well-documented impacts. Risk data were completely checked twice. due to the researcher's relative unfamiliarity with risk analysis and due to poor documentation of sources of information. Benefits data were thoroughly checked once: many of the data were Obtained from the benefits analyses rather than tflua position documents. All together. nearly 8.000 pieces of data were obtained for 86 uses Of the eight pesticides. Copies of the data are on file at Michigan State University Department of Agricultural Economics. -115- Table 4.9 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Toxicity Each Unrebutted Animal Study 2 pts. Each Unrebutted Epidemiological Study (Study of a Human Population) 5 pts. Suggestive Evidence (e.g.. Mutagenicity or Chemical Structures as Suggestive of Oncogenicity) 1 pt. for each category of evidence Table 4.10 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Exposure Residues in food. amount of food consumed. and percent Of crOp treated: Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned = 1 pt. Quantitative. assumed = 2 pts. Quantitative. expert opinion = 3 pts. Study. quantitative range = 4 pts. Study. quantitative point = 5 pts. -116- Table 4.11 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Dermal and Inhalation Exposure Amount of exposure. absorption rate. and duration of exposure: Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned = 1 pt. Quantitative. assumed = 2 pts. Quantitative. expert opinion = 3 pts. Study of similar pesticide. quantitative range = 4 pts. Study of similar pesticide. quantitative point = 5 pts. Study. quantitative range = 6 pts. Study. quantitative point = 7 pts. Table 4.12 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Risk Assessment Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned = 1 pt. Quantitative. range = 2 pts. Quantitative. point = 3 pts. Table 4.13 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Risk Of Alternative Pest Control Ignored or not specifically mentioned 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned 1 pt. Quantitative 2 pts. Table 4.15 -118- Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Significant Decreases in Nontarget Populations Potential Exposure Ignored or not specifically mentioned = Qualitatively mentioned = Quantitative. Quantitative. Study Study Study Study assumed = expert Opinion = of similar pesticide. quantitative range = of similar pesticide. quantitative point = of pesticide. quantitative range = Of pesticide. quantitative point = \lO‘Uluwal-‘O Lethal Dose Required to Kill 50 Percent of Test Animals Ignored or not specifically mentioned = Quantitative. LD50 LDso assumed = for similar species = for species = Likelihood of Exposure Ignored or not specifically mentioned = Qualitatively mentioned = Quantitative. Quantitative. assumed = expert opinion = Theoretical model. quantitative estimate = Study Study Study Study Risk of similar pesticide. quantitative range = of similar pesticide. quantitative point = of pesticide. quantitative range = of pesticide. quantitative point = Ignored or not specifically mentioned = Qualitatively mentioned = Quantitative. range = Quantitative. point = O 1 2 3 CDQO‘U‘ubOJNi-‘O NNHO pts. pt. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pt. pts. pts. pts. pt. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pt. pts. pts. -ll9- Table 4.16 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Fatality to Endangered Species Concentration of Residues Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned = 1 pt. Quantitative. assumed = 2 pts. Quantitative. expert opinion = 3 pts. Theoretical model. quantitative estimate = 4 pts. Monitoring similar species. quantitative range = 5 pts. Monitoring similar species. quantitative point = 6 pts. Monitoring species. quantitative range = 7 pts. Monitoring species. quantitative point = 8 pts. Lethal Doses Required to Kill 50 Percent of Test Animals Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Quantitative. Assumed = 1 pt. LDSO for similar species = 2 pts. L050 for species = 3 pts. Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned = 1 pt. Quantitative. range = 2 pts. Quantitative. point = 3 pts. -120- Table 4.17 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: All Changes in Pest Control Costs and Changes in Value of Production Data Except Price Ignored or not specifically mentioned Qualitatively mentioned Quantitative. assumed Quantitative. expert opinion Study or published data. quantitative range Study or published data. quantitative point U'lnb pts. pt. pts. pts. pts. pts. Table 4.18 Measurement Scale for Quality of Information: Price Ignored or not specifically mentioned Qualitatively mentioned Quantitative. assumed Quantitative. expert Opinion Study. quantitative range Study. quantitative point Quantitative study. varies with quality of commodity Quantitative study. varies with supply of commodity Quantitative study. varies with quality and supply pts. pt. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. pts. Table 4.19 -121- Measurement Scale for Quality of Information Per Acre Change in Pest Control Costs. Total Change in Pest Control Costs. Per Acre Change in Value of Production. Total Change in Value of Production. Change in Other Production Costs. Impacts on Producers of Other Goods. Distribution of Impacts (Users. Nonusers. Marketers. Consumers. Manufacturers). Geographic Impacts. Macroeconomic Impacts. Social Impacts. Degree of Compliance. Costs of Restrictions Ignored or not specifically mentioned = 0 pts. Qualitatively mentioned Quantitative. 1 pt. range = 2 pts. Quantitative. point = 3 pts. Table 4.20 Measurement Scale for EPA Decision Decision Register pesticide = 0 pts. Register with restrictions = 1 pt. Cancel pesticide = 2 pts. -122- Problems in Measuring Dependent Variables. The depend- ent variables were in some ways easier and in some ways harder to measure than the explanatory variables. They were easier because data were being generated rather than sought. If data were unavailable for the explanatory variables. they were unavailable -- the researcher could not go out and measure the acres of apples treated with Amitraz. Measure- ment of the dependent variables was up to the researcher. so there was more control over the quality Of the data. But measuring the dependent variables was difficult because EPA's documentation of information sources was Often poor. there were about 8.000 pieces of data to collect. and the measurement scale for each dependent variable was good but not foolproof. which sometimes led to questions over the value to be assigned to a variable. In general. the bene- fits variables were easier to measure because of better documentation and the researcher's training in economics. Specific comments on risk coding. Specific prob- lems in measuring the risk variables can best be depicted by presenting some of the notes made during the measurement process. These notes are summarized in Table 4.21. General comments on risk coding. The basic approach in coding the dependent risk variables was to strive for consistency within a pesticide over consistency between pesticides. Instead of being straightforward. the risk coding Often ended up as a judgment call after all the information had been compiled. The goal in these situations was to make consistent judgment calls. -123- Table 4.21 Specific Problems in Measuring Dependent Risk Variables Chlorobenzilate 0 Assume that ground application exposure includes ex- posure from mixing and loading. Since absorption was estimated and does not change between routes of exposure. should it be coded for all routes? No. because in many cases those routes of exposure were not even mentioned. When there are inconsistencies between the text and tables. which should be followed? In case of farm- workers. go by text. Is there ever aerial application for cotton. fruits and nuts and "other?” Is there ever farmworker exposure for ”other”? Assumed not. Assumed no dietary exposure from "other" uses. National Cancer Institute study on oncogenicity not reported because it had not been finalized. Toxicity (Adverse Reproductive Effects) was coded as 11 due to 5 studies and suggestive work (1 pt.). Residues in food coded as 2 because detection level was assumed even in the absence of any detected residues. Residues for Florida citrus also given 2 because an assumption was the limiting factor (even though other subcomponents of the data were of a higher quality than a 2). The data source for "food in diet" was simply undocu— mented. Duration of exposure was given a 3 because. although it was a worst-case assumption. it was based on USDA opin- ion. For drift. aerial applicators. noncitrus applicators and farmworkers. there was no mention of absorption and duration. The text simply said that there ”could be exposure.” Therefore. duration and absorption were coded as 0. with exposure getting a l. Assumed that there could be aerial application for Arizona citrus even though no mention. because the text does not say that there is no citrus rust mite in Arizona (only citrus pest for which aerial application was used). -124- Amitraz O Amitraz was exceptionally' well-documented. The only note was that a 2 was assigned to absorption of the chemical. even though the position document mentioned a study on toxicological properties. because there was no documentation of how absorption rates were Obtained. S-T For toxicity. when studies only had preliminary results. they were assigned a 1. Position document 1 was used to code toxicity. O For the percent of crop treated under dietary exposure. a 2 was coded. because EPA appeared to assume that all milk and meat had 2.4.5-T residues. 0 Even though there appeared to be expert opinion on the amount of inhalation exposure to range and handsprayers. a 2 was coded because the expert appeared to have no basis for his statement. It appeared that his statement was an assumption. 0 The amount of dermal exposure to range and handsprayers was given a 1 because. although Dow Chemical provided data. the data was not used by EPA and was difficult to interpret. o The researcher was less confident of the risk data for 2.4.5-T than for other pesticides. Much of the data had to be obtained from position document 1 instead of the PD 2/3. Pronamide o Toxicity received a 3 due to one study and suggestive evidence (on nitrosamines). Endrin 0 Potential exposure to nontarget populations was assigned a 0 in spite of a reference to "environmental effects." because the reference was not specific enough to use as data. O For Endrin use on bird perches and tree paint. exposure to bystanders was coded under exposure via drift. DBCP -125~ Mixer and loader risk was often included in ground applicator exposure. Food residues for alfalfa reported for secondary prod- ucts in the food chain (meat. milk. eggs). Reproductive effects risk analysis for some uses re— ported as margins-Of-safety for individuals consuming quantities of residues. rather than as numbers of re- productive effects per 1000 population. Although quantitative risk analyses were obtained for many exposed groups and uses. there was no mention anywhere of the information used to determine the degree of absorption of inhaled pesticide. Therefore. zeroes were coded. For exposure from spill cleanup under the ”other berries" use. the quantitative risk analysis may have only pertained to raspberries. Dimethoate O Mixer and loader risk was either determined for aerial spray mixers and loaders. or else was included in ground applicator exposure. The risk analysis for reproductive effects on consumers was coded as 3 because the margin-Of-safety for individ- ual consumers was quantified even though the number Of adverse reproductive effects per 1,000 population was not. For alfalfa. food residues in secondary products (meat. milk. eggs) were reported. For lettuce ground applicator duration of dermal ex— posure. the separate benefits analysis was used to determine the quality Of information. It appeared that EPA used an expert opinion on the number of lettuce ground applicators to estimate duration. Silvex Risk information very sketchy in general. For dietary exposure in rice ("food in diet" variable). there was no indication of the source of the data. so the quality of information could not be measured. —126- Another general rule was that if a variable relevant to pesticide use was mentioned qualitatively. but without regard to a specific use of the pesticide. then a zero was coded for that use. This cut down on attempts to disting— uish between the quality of qualitative data -- the measurement scale became cruder. but actual measurement became less crude. It was reasonable to code a zero because information without reference to use was of little or no help to EPA in decision making. The rest of the measurement scale was more straight- forward. The difficulty came in two major areas: 1) Finding EPA's data sources in the position docu- ments. 2) Interpreting the quality of information when there was more than one component to a particular vari- able. For example. "durathmi of exposure" some- times consisted of data on acres treated. time needed to spray one acre. and number of applica- tors. The rule in cases such as this was to use the ”limiting factor" for coding: that is. to code the lowest-quality piece of information for ”dura- tion of exposure.” General comments on benefits coding. Benefits coding was easier because it was more familiar. but also because there tended ix) be better documentation of infor- mation sources. For each pesticide except Chlorobenzilate and Silvex. there was a benefits analysis which supplemented the Position Document 2/3. The additional documents pro- vided a good deal of information that otherwise would not: have been obtained. ~127- The same basic rules used in the risk coding were applied tO the benefits coding. There was one small vari- ation in the "limiting factor" rule: if EPA obtained a number for a benefits variable. the researcher coded the quality of that number. even if it only represented those states or regions responding to a USDA/EPA survey. This decision was made because EPA generally reported the number as representative of the nation in Position Document 2/3. and because generally the number represented most of the product treated with the pesticide. Before ending the discussion of dependent variable coding. it should be mentioned that the initial coding included all of the risk and benefits variables for each regulatory alternative considered by EPA. Since there were as many as seven alternatives for each use of a pesticide. this added several thousands of pieces Of data to the ini- tial coding. The idea had been to determine variations in the quality of information between regulatory options. but the data were terrible and often nonexistent. It did not appear that such an analysis would be meaningful. so the data were not checked in the secondary stages of coding. MANIPULATING DATA FOR COMPARISON BETWEEN PESTICIDES Testing Johnson's hypothesis that greater risk resulted in better information required ranking the pesticides (as opposed to their uses) according to the EPA's definition of risk and then comparing the quality of information between pesticides. (Nu; first task was certainly easier than the second. —128— The ranking according to risk was described earlier in this chapter. But how was the information on dependent variables put into a form that would be comparable between pesticides? The only answer was to average the data across uses for each risk and benefit variable to come up with one number per pesticide per dependent variable. There were several problems with this approach. First. the number of uses varied from 28 (Dimethoate) to 2 (Ami— traz). This meant that for Amitraz. the quality of infor- mation for one use carried far more weight than it did for Dimethoate. It is also possible that EPA had a far more manageable task in Amitraz than it did in Dimethoate. so it was able to obtain better information. 1\ second problem was that a few of the risk variables varied between pesticides. For example. Endrin was the only pesticide for which data on risk to nontarget organisms. wildlife and endangered species were obtained. The Dimeth- oate. Pronamide. Amitraz. Silvex and 2.4.5-T documents measured risk to two or more different types Of ground applicators. and there was no way to know whether to compare handsprayers. tractor .applicators. boom .applicators. com- pressed air applicators. DBCP application did not even involve spraying. The decision was made to leave ground applicators out (u? the analysis of quality of information between pesticides. A third general problem was that there was probably less consistency between pesticides than within each pesticide. -129- In short. more confidence should be placed in the results of the analysis of quality of information within a pesticide. MEASURING CORRELATION BETWEEN DEPENDENT AND EXPLANATORY VARIABLES For each pesticide. correlations were measured between four of the explanatory variables and the quality of each "bit" of risk and benefit information for each HES of the pesticide. As a result. each pesticide has as many poten- tial correlations as there were dependent variables for each Of the four explanatory variables (value of pesticide use to manufacturers. percent of crop treated. annual per acre user losses from pesticide cancellation and annual total user losses from pesticide cancellation. For the fifth explanatory variable. EPA's pesticide risk ranking. the correlation between the variable and the qual- ity of each "bit" of risk and benefit information for each pesticide was measured. As a result. there were only as many correlations as there were dependent variables. Why were the four "interest group" explanatory variables correlated with the quality of risk and benefit information for pesticide pggg? There were several reasons for attempt— ing to explain variation in the quality of information between pggg of a single pesticide. First. it is a matter of control over the research setting. Variation between pesticides could be explained by a wide variety of varia— bles. such as different levels of resources. different researchers. different costs of information. and. Of course. -130- different levels of interest group pressure. But within a single pesticide. most of those variables do not vary. Thus. there are fewer non-hypothesized reasons for variation in the quality of information between uses of a pesticide. In short. the research setting is more controlled. Another reason for examining variation between uses rather than between pesticides is that there are some major difficulties in measuring dependent variables (quality Of information) for a pesticide. These problems were discussed earlier in reference to the EPA's pesticide risk ranking explanatory variable. In general. the average quality of information across all uses of a pesticide may not accur- ately reflect the overall quality of information for the pesticide. Finally. examining variation between uses of a pesticide is interesting from a research perspective. Interest group incentives vary at least as widely between uses as between pesticides. But constraints (”1 decision-making presumably do not. .As a result the research question becomes one of’ how EPA and interest groups allocate their scarce informa- tion resources between pesticide uses within the particular regulatory environment that is characteristic of an indi- vidual pesticide. There are two widely-accepted statistics used to measure correlation between explanatory and dependent variables when one variable is measured cardinally and the other ordinally. -131- The first statistic to measure the relationship between an explanatory and a: dependent variable is called multiserial correlation. This statistic assumes that one variable is measured ordinally and the other on an interval scale. It also assumes that the ordinal scale variables (in this re- search. the quality of information variables) would approx— imate a normal distribution if they could be measured more precisely on an interval scale and that there is a linear relationship between the explanatory' and dependent vari— ables. Basically. multiserial correlation accurately trans- forms the ordinal scale into an interval scale if the or- dinal scale variables are normally distributed. Once this is done. an adapted version of "Pearson's r" is calculated to show the degree of correlation. Goodman and Kruskal's coefficient of ordinal association (called the "gamma coefficient") can be used either when both variables are measured ordinally or when one is meas- ured cardinally and the other ordinally. The gamma coeffi- cient was chosen for this research for several reasons. First. the explanatory variables were measured crudely. and actually ordinally when the EPA described them qualitative- ly. Given that. it would probably be risky to consider them as being measured cardinally (which would be a requirement of multiserial correlation). Second. there is no reason to believe that the data for each dependent variable would approximate the normal distribution needed for accurate measures of correlation using multiserial correlation. The -l32- quality of information for a particular impact of pesticide use tended to be incremetal between uses of a pesticide (and thus. fairly constant). so there was not always a clustering of data points towards the center of the scale. A third reason for choosing gamma is that the measure of correlation was intended to serve as a guide to the nature of the relationships between the quality of information and the various explanatory variables. Gamma serves that pur- pose: multiserial correlation provides a more precise measure that may not be justified by the data. Fourth. when testing Edwin Johnson's statement that risk drives the risk- benefit analysis. the explanatory variable (“risk of pesti- cide“) and dependent variables were measured ordinally. so multiserial correlation could not be used. The use of gamma to measure the other hypotheses provided consistency in the research. In short. use of the more complex and precise multiserial correlation probably could not have been de- fended because of the quality of the data collected for explanatory and dependent variables. A programmable calculator was used to calcuate the gamma coefficients in this research. The data for dependent and explanatory variables were entered by hand. and each gamma coefficient was checked at least once (at least three times if the first and second answers did not agree). To calcu- late gamma. pesticide uses were ranked from highest value to lowest value of a particular explanatory variable. ~133- The formula to calculate the gamma coefficient is: (number of agreements in direction of changes for explana- tory and dependent variables - number of inversions) + (num- ber of agreements + number of inversions). Gamma can range from -l.O to +1.0: if there is no variation in the dependent variables. gamma is indeterminant and cannot be calculated. Examples of gamma coefficient calculations to explain varia- tion between 3222 of a pesticide and to explain variation between pesticides can be found in Tables 4.22 and 4.23. Once all of the gammas were calculated. they had to be evaluated. Ini general. non-zero gammas of less than .250 and greater than -.250 were considered to show very weak correlations. given the quality of the data. Tables in Chapters 5 and 6 show the frequencies of gammas with differ- ent values for each dependent variable. For the four vari- ables explaining variation in the quality of information between pesticide 2335. the tables also show the number of pesticides with primarily positive and negative gammas for risk and benefit categories. These summaries of the vast number of gammas calculated will serve as the basis for the evaluation and interpretation of the results. SUMMARY The methodology described in this chapter is complica- ted. not because of complex statistical techniques. but because of the amount of data. the measurement difficulties and the shortage of similar methodologies in previous re— search. What follows is a brief summary of the methodology used in this research. -l34- Table 4.22 Calculation of Gamma Coefficient for Chlorobenzilate: Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers and Consumer Risk of Oncogenicity Value of Use Consumer Risk — Oncogenicity 233 to Manufacturers Florida Citrus $3.220.000 Texas Citrus $406.000 Cotton $212.550 California Citrus $30.000 Arizona Citrus $24.000 Other $100* Fruits and Nuts ? * Value assigned for "little use” Number of decreases in consumer risk of oncogenicity as value of use decreases: Number of increases in consumer risk of oncogenicity as value of use decreases: Gamma = 0-3 = = -1 _- :2 0+3 3 2 3 not applicable 3 3 not applicable 3 -l35- Table 4.23 Calculation of Gamma Coefficient for EPA's Pesticide Risk Ranking and Consumer Risk of Oncogenicity EPA Risk Consumer Risk - Pesticide Ranking Oncogenicity Endrin 21 not applicable Chlorobenzilate 13 2.8 DBCP 13 3.0 Dimethoate 12 1.0 Silvex 7 0.8 2.4.5-T 7 1.0 Amitraz 7 3.0 Pronamide 6 2.7 Number of decreases in consumer risk of oncogenicity as EPA risk ranking decreases: 10 Number of increases in consumer risk of oncogenicity as EPA risk ranking increases: 5 Gamma = 10-5 = 5 = .33 10+5 l -l36- Explanatory variables were defined to reflect the incen— tives of interest groups to involve themselves in the poli— tical process. Four of the variables were measured for each use of each pesticide. using EPA's Position Document 2/3s. The fifth variable. ”EPA's Risk Ranking“. was measured for each pesticide with EPA data. The dependent variables reflected the quality of EPA's information on risks and benefits for each use of each pesticide. Measurement scales were devised by reading EPA's position documents and benefits analyses. and values were then assigned to the variables. Correlations between the explanatory variables and the dependent variables were measured by Goodman and Kruskal's coefficient of ordinal association (“gamma”). In order to make the dependent variables comparable with EPA's pesticide risk ranking which was only obtained for each pesticide. the quality of information was averaged across all uses of each pesticide. Thus. one gamma was calculated for each depend- ent variable. For the other four explanatory variables. gammas were calculated for each dependent variable and each pesticide. as correlation between explanatory variables and the quality of information for uses of a pesticide were estimated. CHAPTER 5 RESULTS: QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON RISK OF PESTICIDE USE INTRODUCTION There are three main Objectives of Chapter 5n First. there are some general comments and qualitative examples of EPA's risk assessment process. Second. the quality Of EPA's risk information is summarized. And finally. the relation- ships between the explanatory variables. as measured. and the quality of EPA's risk information are summarized. OVERVIEW OF EPA'S RISK ASSESSMENT PROCESS EPA's risk assessments tend to be incremental in nature from one pesticide to another (although not to the same extent as the benefits assessments. due to differences in risk between pesticides). As a result. there are some general trends in the risk assessment process. First. it is important to point out that EPA has a definite stake in protecting the findings of its preliminary risk analysis. The preliminary risk analysis initiates the RPAR process and often serves as the basis for the final risk assessment contained in Position Document 2/3. If the preliminary analysis is not correct in its projection of "unacceptable risk." then why was so much time (often two years or more at the rebuttal stage of the process) and money invested in studying the pesticide? Perhaps this -137- -138- accounts for the apparent antagonistic relationship between EPA and the registrants and EPA's own defensiveness. which are evident even on the pages of the public documents re- sulting from the RPAR process. However. EPA's commitment to its preliminary risk analy- sis does not extend to doing in-house toxicity and exposure studies. at least for the eight case-study pesticides. No doubt this is due to a lack of appropriated funds. but it means that EPA has to rely on data from outside groups. When registrants submit exposure or toxicity data that would lower EPA's risk calculations. it does not seem to be greeted by EPA with the same enthusiasm as data that increases the risk calculations or benefits data from users. For example. when Dow Chemical Company provided information on applicator exposure to the herbicide 2.4.5-T during forestry applications. EPA supposedly used the information to revise its risk analysis. However. no evidence of re- vision could be found in the public documents. One of EPA's reservations in using the data was that the forestry use was not being considered in the 2.4.5-T RPAR. so extrapolation of the exposure data across uses would have to occur. However. EPA often uses exposure data from other pesticides. as well as other uses. in its risk analysis. The 2.4.5-T risk analysis was no exception. It may be relevant to point out that the 2.4.5-T RPAR was the most hotly contested of the eight case-study chemicals. -l39- What about data from the groups which bear the risk? Risk-bearing groups are. in general. very diffuse. unin- formed and unorganized. Information on exposure and toxicity of pesticides is very costly to Obtain (often because such information has not yet been compiled). In addition. risk-bearing groups often contain large numbers of geographically-dispersed members. which results in high organization costs. The theories of Stigler and Peltzman would predict that these groups would gain little (or lose a lot) in the decision-making process due to their inability to impact regulators. However. as van Ravenswaay (1982) points out. these groups' political costs may be subsidized by ”political entrepreneurs.“ (see also Wilson (1980)) who are able to influence decision-making. In the RPAR process. the two major political entrepreneurs for risk-bearing groups appear to be the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF) and the EPA itself. Part of the EPA's activism is built into the process -- since a determination of risk is needed to initiate the RPAR process. EPA has a stake in defending its risk findings. And while the environmental groups such as EDF are not highly visible during all regulatory activities for all pesticides. they may very well reserve their own limited resources for controversial. high-risk pesticides -- the very pesticides which they should have the most success in affecting regulatory outcomes. \ _..-.‘ y {I / ., j Another characteristic of EPA's risk assessment process p//// is the need to bound the problem and develop standard oper- ating procedures in order to cope with the potentially infinite information requirements of pesticide regulation. van Ravenswaay and Hull (1981) describe many of EPA's standard Operating procedures when they discuss strategies for meeting information requirements in food safety regula- tion. In estimating risk. EPA usually determines toxicity .&’//// of a chemical from high-dosage animal tests rather than human studies. Margins of safety are used when extra— polating animal tests to humans. in case humans are more sensitive to a chemical than the test animals. Exposure to different groups of humans is estimated by using the same sources all of the time -— Food and Drug Administration ”Market Basket Surveys" for pesticide residues in food. a small group of studies on applicator exposure (Often data from other pesticides are used). data from registrants and user groups. and assumptions on exposure. Extrapolation of ,1 risk from high doses given to test animals to relatively low doses experienced by humans is accomplished by using math- ematical models of dose-response. In all of the case studies for this research. EPA uses the model which usually results in the highest prediction of risk. The “one-hit” model assumes that very minimal doses of a chemical present some risk of chronic illness. It is difficult to estimate the direction of the bias of L/' these strategies on risk estimates. Risk estimation is ,* ffl\}‘)x {/-l4l;/;J \xw/fl/ characterized by such uncertainty that it is impossible to know whether EPA's estimates are high or low. EPA's inclin- ation is definitely toward erring on the side of safety. but what if humans are much more sensitive to a chemical than animals? What if exposure estimates are too low? What about more sensitive members of the population or people with above-average exposure? It is conceivable that a risk estimate is too low even with EPA's bias toward safety. Along with simplifying the information search. EPA also reduces or "bounds" problems. as suggested by Edmunds (1980). Problems are reduced by excluding certain impacts from consideration -— EPA excludes the impacts of pesticide use (N1 chemical manufacturing workers (who are supposedly covered under the Occupational Safety and Hazard Act). exposure to other chemicals which may enhance or lower the impacts of the pesticide in question. certain relationships ix: the ecosystem. auui other risk variables. All of this represents an effort by EPA to make the problem of pesticide regulation comprehensible and manageable. However. as willyJ/,x“‘ be pointed out in the next section. EPA's existing risk information still leaves a lot to be desired. \\,//”‘ The internal structure of EPA's Office Of Pesticide Programs (OPP) also reveals a lot about which impacts are included in risk-benefit analysis and which are not. 'The Hazard Evaluation Division within OPP. largely responsible for the risk assessment. is composed of a Toxicology Branch. an Environmental Fate Branch. a Residue Chemistry Branch -l42- and an Ecological Effects Branch. Figure 5.1 shows what is ideally accounted for by each branch. but in reality many impacts of pesticide use are excluded. QUALITY OF EPA'S RISK INFORMATION Table 5.1 summarizes the quality of more than 5.500 EPA risk data. as measured by the researcher. In addition to the data summarized. there are many other risk character— istics that EPA did not attempt to measure for any of the eight pesticides. as pointed out in Chapters 3 and 4. Table 5.1 does not show high—quality information under- lying EPA's risk assessments. In the three major measure— ment categories. EPA ignores risk variables in the great majority of cases. For the dietary exposure category. where 76.812 percent of the variables were not even mentioned. most of the zero scores resulted from EPA's failure to acknowledge dietary exposure as an additional residue source for ground applicators. mixers and loaders. pilots. ground crews. farmworkers. and persons exposed to spills or drift. But in the second and third categories. the zero scores resulted from EPA's failure to mention aspects of dermal and inhalation exposure and risk to various groups. The minor categories do not vary much from the three major ones. Most of the measures are congregated around the zero and one scores. Another tendency reflected in Table 5.1 is EPA's avoid— ance of quantitative range estimates. even for the risk measures. When quantitative estimates were made. they were -l43- Component HED Branch Background Chemical and physical properties Environmental fate and persistence Human exposure analysis Dermal Respiratory Dietary (food and water) Inhalation. penetration and absorption rates Human health risk Cancer Acute toxicity Other chronic toxicity Ecological hazard Residue Chemistry Environmental Fate Environmental Fate Environmental Fate Residue Chemistry Toxicology CAG.* Toxicology Toxicology Toxicology Ecological Effects *Not a branch of HED. Source: Environmental Studies Board Committee on Prototype Explicit Analyses for Pesticides. Regulating Pesti- cides (Washington. D.C.: National Research Council. 1980). p. 38. Figure 5.1 Components of Pesticide Principal Organizational Responsibilities in the Risk Assessment Office of Pesticide Programs -l44- Table 5.1 Quality Of Risk Information Measure- Variables ment Meaning of Fre- Percent Measured Scale Measure quency Of Total -Dietary Exposure 5 quantitative. 106 6.679% (Residues. Food point in Diet. Percent 4 quantitative. O 0% Crop Treated) range 3 expert Opinion 94 5.923% 2 assumption 134 8.444% 1 qualitative 34 2.142% 0 ignored 1219 76.812% -Dermal & Inhala- 7 study of pesti- 88 3.039% tion Exposure cide. point (Amount. Absorp- 6 study of pesti— 4 .138% tion. Duration) cide. range 5 study Of similar 130 4.489% -Residues & Amount situation. point Of Food Consumed 4 study Of similar 4 .138% for Acute Toxi- situation. range city to Wildlife 3 expert Opinion 187 6.457% 2 assumption 273 9.427% —Potential Exposure 1 qualitative 201 6.941% for Nontarget Or- 0 ignored 2009 69.372% ganisms -Risk (Consumers. 3 quantitative. 172 14.576% Ground Applica- point tors. Mixers & 2 quantitative. 12 1.017% Loaders. Ground range Crews. Drift. l qualitative 429 36.356% Spills. Pilots. 0 ignored 567 48.051% Farmworkers. Wildlife. Non- target Organ- isms. Endangered Species) -LD (Wildlife. 3 L05 . species 3 11.538% Nontarget Or- 2 L050. similar 3 11.538% ganisms. Endan- species gered Species) l assumed 0 0% 0 ignored 20 76.923% -145- Measure- Variables ment Meaning of Fre- Percent Measured Scale Measure quency of Total -Risk of Alterna- 2 quantitative 0 0% tive Pest Control 1 qualitative 42 55.263% Method 0 ignored 34 44.737% -Likelihood of 8 study of pesti- 0 0% Exposure for cide. point Nontarget Or- 7 study of pesti- 2 12.500% ganisms cide. range 6 similar situation. 0 0% -Concentration of point Residues for 5 similar situation. 0 0% Endangered range Species 4 theoretical model 1 6.250% 3 expert opinion 0 0% 2 assumed 0 0% l qualitative 7 43.750% 0 ignored 6 37.500% ~146- almost always point estimates. This does not necessarily reflect greater precision in EPA's estimates and supporting data -n- it could possibly reflect pressure from within and without the agency to come up with definite numbers to aid or justify decisions. In general. it can be said that EPA's risk data for the eight case-study pesticides were not complete. and when present. not usually a result of quantitative studies Of the pesticide. Instead. measurements tended to be based on expert opinions. assumptions. or studies of other chemicals. CORRELATION BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND QUALITY OF RISK INFORMATION VARIABLES This portion of the Chapter examines the extent of cor- relation. as measured by gamma (G). between the hypothesized explanatory variables and the quality of information used by EPA to assess the risk of the 86 uses of the 8 pesticides. One of two results was found for each potential gamma. If there was no variation in the quality of risk information for all of a pesticide's uses that could be measured for a particular explanatory variable. then there was no G -- by' definition. it was undefined. Otherwise. a G in the range of -l to +1 was found. Explanation Of Tables. Although it would facilitate the analysis of the research findings. it would be misleading to use a single number to summarize all of these correlations. Instead. Tables 5.3 through 5.7 were devised from Tables 1 -l47- through 44 in Appendix B to summarize for each explanatory variable: O the numbers and values of gamma coefficients that could be calculated for exposure and risk. within each Of nine risk categories. 0 when gamma coefficients could not be calculated (i.e.. when there was no variation in the quality of risk data between uses of a pesticide). the quality of risk information for exposure and risk. within each of the nine risk categories. O the total possible numbers of gamma coefficients for risk and exposure. within each of the nine risk categories. O the number of pesticides for which one or more gamma coefficients could be calculated. for each of? the nine risk categories. Unless otherwise noted. the number is the total out of a possible eight pesticides. o for each of the nine risk categories. the number Of pesticides with primarily positive gammas. pri- marily negative gammas. and equal numbers of posi- tive and negative gammas. The nine risk categories are consumers. ground applica- tors. mixers and loaders. pilots. persons exposed to drift. farmworkers. persons exposed to spills. aerial ground crews and animals. Exposure refers to dietary exposure for con~ sumers: dermal. inhalation and dietary exposure for the —l48- seven other human risk categories: and animal exposure. Risk refers to oncogenic. mutagenic. and fetotoxic and reproductive risk to humans. and animal risk. In describing the values of the gammas that could be calculated. the following measurement scale was devised: -1 to .-750 -.749 to —.500 —.499 to —.250 -.249 to O .001 to .250 .251 to .500 .501 to .750 .751 to 1 This particular measurement scale was chosen in part because the researcher felt that gammas between the values of -.249 and +.250 could not be considered strongly positive or nega- tive. given the limitations in measuring explanatory and dependent variables. Tables 5.3 through 5.7 show the fre— quency of gamma values for exposure and risk within each of the nine risk categories. Gammas that could not be calculated were designated with a "--". Since this reflects no variation in the quality of information between uses of a pesticide. the number in parentheses shows the quality of information for all uses of a pesticide that can be measured for the particular explana- tory variable. When a "--(x)" is left blank for a risk category (as opposed to showing a zero). the number in the —149- parentheses is not included in the measurement scale for those particular risk or exposure variables. In addition. "—-(?)" means that the quality of information for at least half of the uses of the pesticide could not be determined. The "total possible G" line in each table is the sum of the gammas that could be calculated and those that could not be calculated. It is useful because it shows how Often (or perhaps. how seldom) there was variation in the quality of information between uses an) that gammas could actually be calculated. The lower half of each table reflects the number of pesticides that showed positive. negative or ambiguous relationships between the explanatory variable and the quality of information for each of the nine risk categories. This was determined by simply summing the positive and negative gammas and comparing the two sums. These figures show whether a large number of positive gammas in a risk category reflect many positive gammas for one pesticide. or a positive trend for several pesticides. It is the positive trend for several pesticides that will reflect the kind of correlation that was hypothesized between the explanatory variable and the quality of information for a particular risk category. In the body of the table. the numbers in parentheses denote the frequency of "lower range" gammas in each of the eight ranges for the value of gamma. Lower range and upper range gammas occur because for some pesticides. the uses -150- could only be measured in ranges for the explanatory vari- ables. Using the high point of the range to rank uses within a pesticide according to one of the explanatory variables led to different values for gamma than if the low point of the range was used. Therefore. "lower range” and “upper range” gammas must be reported. Table 5.2 is also useful in interpreting the results found in Tables 5.3 through 5.6. This table shows the total number of uses of each pesticide. and the number of uses that can be measured for each of four explanatory variables. Gammas based on very few uses of a pesticide are not as reliable as gammas based on most uses. For example. for the ”value of use to manufacturer” variable only 3 of 11 uses of Endrin could be measured. Therefore. all gammas measuring the correlations between the value of Endrin uses to man- ufacturers and the quality of Endrin risk/benefit informa- tion are based on only three uses of the pesticide. On the other hand. 17 of 18 DBCP uses could be measured according to value of uses to manufacturers. Presumably. the DBCP gammas would be more reliable than the Endrin gammas. Findings for Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers. The explanatory variable ”value of a pesticide use to manu- facturer” is intended to proxy the likelihood of manufac- turers to become vigorously involved in the information— gathering phase of the regulatory process. Pesticide man- ufacturers seem to fit the Stigler/Peltzman mold for a grOUp that can impact the regulatory process. There are generally -151- .mms one as mchum HHS-n you summon-“se.. o)» ecu sou-500 umcuumonmu ecu .oHcmHug amour-Baum come now owumngm mum: moms hams soc mchHsuwumc no memonusa ecu mom .mumwe LOMus can named nocHs oucH ems gmchum HHS-m: ecu DHHem mes-Huge cem- .monomusm uHumcmc mom £9639.- .mwms HH mmc fine-B 0303mm.“ ecu. N .wms oco oucH somemHHoo mums hmcu cmsocu cw>w .moms wusuumH m HHm emucsoo umcoumwmwu ecu .mecmHum> 03D mnocu ou mcHeuooom consumes meemcoum no men: we noses: ecu mcHucsoo cmcz .mco an uncommon condone who: moms mosuuwH m HHm Keen-m8”. mono no accesses can sums-3035:8- ou ems no 8H8? mcHusmme-e CH .xcdmumowm.>c1>Hco mums coch wosuuwH :0 men: one cOch uo m .nwms oH mac meEmcomm meHuHunwm ace H me vs Os no mo chmusnmoz memo Hmuoe N N N N N nmuuHE¢ N m N m m 91m .e .N m o m N h xm>HHm m m h w h mumHHNcwcouoHco o m Hm HOH oH HmeHsmcoum h s OH m HH NcHuecm vN 5N oN vN mN wumocumEHo 5H mH mH 5H mH mono .cmo «censuses couumaflmocmo emanate mumusuomuscmz ou saw >9 pmumsHm>m monoaumma some nwmmoq mcHOHummm nouu no on: no wsHm> new: no uwcssz ammo Hence scum monmoa ucmuuwm mono shoe use ”cu mchuooud concern: memo mo umcEsz neHcmHum> wuoumcdexm ou mcHeuooo< mcHuHumem comm now enhance: memo no uwcssz N.m chmH It. m m l:- Aerial gun madam. hpmnluk hpflnIuk utuath-aflubninpnMMuahmuluurupthan) Mun hum-u- Nhu pudtswut upmnluklwauaut human: tum Gnu-n Amuauu mdudus Iwunluklwaueud annuluk tfle&3tunneluuuuuubuuQOHBQOtudnua-dunsdlaud.Uheehmhauu “6 «000000.! 000—00000 00000000 0000000!~ #0000000 #0000000 00000000 00000000 M0000NON “00000.00 d0000fl00 00000000 H000000fl Hoooeooq 00000609 00-002000“ GOOOOOGA NOOOHOOA agaofi§§ .. a s all. {3333333 3 H .iiifiiai -152- 0000I-O0000 000000050-0 HOF0=0 00000006!‘ ”---- AAAAAAAAA U N 00-00 «N ”8° 00000 ooHooHN3—o H0000 -00N00'030 0100-000 N0d00fi0:0 H0—0N0 HOH0000a0 fl0h00 .00400040 ---”---U- 1 1 2 1 hiapuwhilhtapuuhll fi‘um‘hflkuu htamuhh6)htapuuu7) M uninuuuc at arummccmu hedwhud “tuna“ uMaruk Raga-nu mdunch ducnnuflnn upmnueud maunch “wan-nu mpuncm m human- flhu padtokut Mun manna: ufluwhu Inauaua upmnluklwaaaud hmunfluklmuuent Idmulnln(mmcsmpunmuudmaakarma-awn» tad tflehdlunqwtauuuu.bun—ODHQ1IM‘InI-lhuntd1upuuhl Gnu-n OHOHOHOO OHHnHNOG oooeoooo 00000d00 00000fld0 #0000000 00000000 000000dfl 00000Hdfl 000000d0 00000NNN "FOOHOHOCO EOOBOHOH “#00fl000 Aha“ 'oe'voo' N 3 ° NO0HOH00 -153- 00N00 OONOONQRH d0dz0 00000003H ---”- oonoonnsu «ONVO 00N000fla0 HOMOO NOHO0F030 HOHOO d0d000030 fl0h00 ------ ”U”- --- M hulhuuhc It mhuothukuu S C 3 3 Hi 0 C 26. Ni N 3 i 3. 0 N B n 0 N saga-nu u’uuch 2 dueunnfluu «manna-a U’flflfl? -154- o u o o o a a a o ..o .58... ...... 9:38.. no . is. «It 51. o o a a o o o . o u so 338! adult-— 5:. a a o a n a a a v .6 8318 ashlar. 51. 233-85.3.3931-8. ...-3138352.! Inna)!- ~ « a n n a n o ... 2589.. .3 33.28 ... 3:8 o 62.. .8 13oz...- uo as]... a o a 8. 3 2. 3 2. 2 8 «a 8 3 3 8 8 3 8 9.888.... 38 o o o I 3 a. a 3 a a s 8 3 2. v a a 3 g o o o a o a 8. o 8. o o a o o o 8 o a o v E I o o o B 3 6 a. n .3. a v 8 v a a 3 o 3 o a 3. I o o o o u o .3 a .3 a a a a a a a a a a u 3 I o o o o o a 8. o E a o a o v o a o c o v a. I o o o o a o 5 a .3 n o o a o a o a a v a a. I o o o .o. o o o o o o .3 I o o o 5 a a a a n v a. I o o o 8. o o o o o 3. I o o o 3 a o o a a E I a n » ... 2 v 3 a o 3 3 n o 33.3 n I a a n 3. n a 3 as. 3. O 80. 3 3m. 3. o 3. o ..N. N 2.. h 3. o 3. o 3. N 3. N AN. N 3. o 3. o 3. N 3. a 3. a 3. a an. A M u w 3. 0 8n. 3 3N. o 3. o 3. n 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. a 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o .N. o 3. o 3. o 3. N 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o .N. a 3. N AN. n .N. n 3. 0 AN. 0 3. c 3. o 3. n :4. a A .N. N .N. n 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. a 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. a 3. u an. N 3. n 3. h 3. o 3N. nu a 3. n SN. 3 «8. 3. a 3. N 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. u 3. o .N. o 3. n 3. u 3. v 3n. «N 3. 3. N o 8 a... 3. o 3. o 3. n 3. o 3. u 3. u 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. n 3. «a 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. a 8N... on a”... 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. a 3.. n 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. N 3. u g... 3 2.: 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. n .N. N 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. o 3. 0 A... o 3. a 02.... 3 7 gull!!- 33 a; a; a; gill} a; gallon] a; 03 3|?- Ildoflfldgsoll 53833338.. 33: 2.8.8!- 88838- lilac .3! 3n.- uli nan-888 ...—I... I!!! .§33§%5§.!35 igizgigaikigéfii «Jail ~155- AH ognamwoa 9 ac. a 3 3398a o ”3 a a n N as caauuooa a any Au can“ saoug ~ 83888 no ~83: o o 0 Be 2.3.9.. 9... 338: no Eillialfig o N a 30,358 zquhfig n v v -..o .2538.- btlvu. .3: 138?: n w n .iiuaha . 0338708 3350fi53kfl 3 a z a 3 «0 ON a a on Osa'gnaa O O 9 2 8' :1 33 a h ‘ 8 On 1888 0 III g V Ff on H H 00000 0 000000000 sen Rvfl 3v~ :vo avw Svo ave ave OOOONHO O CONDO OOOMOOOO 8. o 8. o o a... n 33 on v .8 n .3 n 8. o .2 u 8. H .3 ~ .2 o 3 a .8 o 3» n O OONOONnR—a HOHHO an H OOOOOMOBfl 00“ H M F M OOOGOOOO OOOdOOOO OOOHOOOO HOOOOOON MOOOOOO' OOOOOOHN '0 OOMOOMnso-o GOOD-«OHM HONVO OOOMOOHO 3 bONOOQNgO OOOGONNN 3*! 3?‘ 3f] 3*l 37' 37' 3.- 37' NOWDO O noncoa~33 NONOO 9 HOmONDsz. QOhOO VOHVNHV n .‘9. n o Asap. omosnao oaosnn. SQOHSQ Gama? Qflfsmcf aquamxf afitsul OOOOVOOH OOOOflOOH OOONFOOF A II. o-O U n d 000MHNOM xfluegag {Hugsflu {HIBSQHxaugaafi {Hollauxflagaaa 1393899133838” ‘ansanu Duo 3.55 8209.38 3:..u3u88 gangs—88a 303.. 83 #324 raise; Ialsal Eildil .332 .3538 .3, 83? Sixv :8g3ogfluggc88033553n3g8i3.Ildixiii J‘Sulaifw135u513a*§303330813a8327§899bllu0603' -156- few major manufacturers of a pesticide (meaning low organi- zation costs) and the financial stakes can be very high. Stigler and Peltzman have hypothesized that the more the regulated parties have at stake, the more they will affect. the regulatory process. In this research, it is hypothe- sized that manufacturers of a pesticide will improve the quality of information on the benefits and risks of the morte valuable uses of that pesticide. Likewise, it is hypothe- sized that the manufacturers will spend less time and fewer' resources in attempts to gather information on risk for less valuable uses of the pesticide. The results do not, in general, support these hypo- theses. For seven of the nine risk categories, a vast majority of the gammas could not be calculated (that is, the quality of information in those categories did not usually vary between uses of the various pesticides). The two risk categories for which a majority of gammas could be calcu- lated, ground applicators and animals, showed two different results. The ground applicator category showed 25 of 42 positive gammas in the .751 to 1 range, which indicates strong posi- tive correlations. Only 14 gammas were not positive, of which 13 were in the -.249 to 0 range. Furthermore, all six of the pesticides for which one or more gammas could be calculated had primarily positive gammas. Ground applicator risk is the most important risk category in EPA's studies, with the possible exception of consumer risk. -157— The animal risk category showed mixed results for tflue one pesticide to which it applied, Endrin. There were equal numbers of strongly negative and strongly positive gammas: and the remaining gamma was in the -.249 to 0 range. As a result, Endrin just barely ended up in the primarily nega- tive group for the animal risk category. About all that can really be said for the remaining risk categories is that gamma could not usually be calculated. When it could not, the quality of information across all uses of a pesticide was usually zero (i.e., the risk was ignored), except for consumers. This is partly because dietary exposure for all non-consumer human risk categories was usually ignored. Thus, the hypothesized relationship was not supported by empirical results. Quality of risk data tended not to vary at all, and when it did, the results were ambiguous when compared with the value of pesticide uses to manufacturers. What could cause these results? One potential cause could be that manufacturers do not want to see better information in EPA's risk analyses. Vague or poor information could result in a better regulatory outcome for manufacturers. A second potential explanation is that pesticide manufacturers are unable to impact EPA's risk analyses. This explanation would seem to fly in the face of Peltzman and Stigler's work. A third potential explanation is that the manufac- turers allocated their scarce resources towards securing better information on ground applicator risk because EPA ~158- spends most of its resources on that risk category. This would make even more sense if the manufacturers perceived that EPA based its decisions on findings of ground appli- cator risk. The manufacturers may simply feel that they get the most value for their information expenditures by con- centrating on the high-risk ground applicator category, and then saving the rest of their resources for improving the quality of benefits information. Findings for Percent of Crgp Treated. The ”percent of crop treated” explanatory variable is intended to proxy the number of pesticide users affected by EPA's regulatory actions. It is hypothesized in this research that as a larger number or proportion of users are affected, the quality of risk information will increase as those users impact the regulatory process. Stigler and Peltzman might argue that the organization costs of larger groups might hinder the ability of the groups to affect the process, but it is hypothesized that the presence of political entrepre- neurs such as USDA and well-organized user groups eliminates organization costs. Once again, the results do not seem to support the hypothesis. The only risk categories for which a majority of the total possible gammas could be calculated were ground applicators and animals. When G could not be calculated, the quality of risk information was usually zero for every risk category except consumers (that is, the particular exposure or risk variable was usually ignored by EPA). ~159- The numbers of pesticides with primarily positive, nega- tive or mixed gammas did not suggest a particular relation- ship between the percent of crop treated and the quality of risk data for any of the nine risk categories. What could cause these results? Perhaps pesticide users do not necessarily want to improve risk information, especially if better information is perceived as leading to more restrictions on pesticides. Pesticide users may also be ground applicators and the profit motive may overrule any desire to see stronger information and regulations to reduce ground applicator risk. Users certainly have a better handle on benefits information, so they may focus their efforts in that direction, instead of trying to influence risk information. Finally, EPA probably attempts to defend its risk analysis from external information that undermines the findings. 'This should be more true for risk than for benefit information because USDA has major responsibility for preparing the benefits analysis. Although the overall results showed no clear trend when G could be calculated, that was not the case for individual pesticides. Some pesticides showed primarily positive Gs for a risk category, others showed primarily negative Gs and still others showed equal numbers of positive and negative Gs. The two pesticides with the most measurable uses for percent of crap treated showed opposite results. The per- cent of DBCP uses treated was positively correlated with the -160- quality of DBCP risk information for the three risk cate- gories for which DBCP Gs could be calculated. On the other hand, Dimethoate showed negative Gs for the five risk cate— gories for which Gs could be calculated. Apparently, the percent of crop treated influenced risk information within some pesticides, but not others. But the overwhelming result for this explanatory vari- able was that there usually was no variation in the quality of risk information between pesticide uses. In general, when there was no variation, the quality of information was zero. Thus, EPA tended to ignore many aspects of risk. Findings for Annual Per Acre User Losses. The "annual per acre user losses” variable was intended to proxy poten- tial per capita user losses from pesticide cancellation. In accordance with the Stigler and Peltzman theories, it is hypothesized that attempts to influence the regulatory process, and thus the quality of risk information, will increase as per acre user losses increase. The results, as shown in Table 5.5, are somewhat more positive than for the previous explanatory variables. For all risk categories except persons exposed to spills, there appears to be some relationship between per acre user losses and quality of risk information. One good reason for these results could be that EPA gathers good information to defend the risk of those pesticide uses with higher potential per capita user losses. Greater economic benefits presumably mean fewer restrictions for a pesticide use, unless EPA can -161- show a greater likelihood of risk. Another potential ex- planation which is more in keeping with Stigler and Peltzman is that pesticide users become more involved in the regula- tory process as per capita stakes increase, resulting in better risk information for the uses with higher annual per acre user losses. But still, in most cases, there was no variation between pesticide uses in the quality of risk information. More often than not, EPA ignored risk variables -- the quality of risk information for pesticide uses that could be measured according to annual per acre user losses was not good. Findings for Annual Total User Losses. The final explan- atory variable to describe variation in the quality of information between BEE of a pesticide was "annual total user losses." This variable is intended to measure the potential industry-wide impacts of pesticide cancellation. The hypothesis is that as the aggregate value of a pesticide use to users increases, the quality of risk information will increase as pesticide users or their political entrepreneurs become involved in the regulatory process. It should be noted that there is a difference between per acre and total user losses. It is often the case that a low-volume, low total user losses use of a pesticide has high per acre user impacts. Examining both variables can provide insight into whether EPA and pesticide advocates react more to aggregate or individual economic impacts. ~162- The results in Table 5.6 are similar to the results for annual per acre user losses. Based on numbers of pesticides with primarily positive Gs, there appears to be a positive correlation between annual total user losses and quality of information for six of the nine risk categories, and for the two major categories (consumers and ground applicators). In addition, where there are pesticides with primarily negative Gs, the negative Gs are almost always in the weakly negative -.249 to 0 range. Again, EPA may seek to obtain better risk information when it knows the risk findings will be balanced against high potential benefits of a pesticide use. Likewise, the pesticide users themselves will encourage better information if they feel that the information will result in findings of lower risk. If the latter explanation is true, it appears that the user groups can overcome any political organization costs in many instances -— this could reflect the presence of political entrepreneurs or already-organized user groups. However, it is possible that organization costs prevented user groups from having an even larger impact on the quality of information: hence, the failure to see more positive Gs. As for all of the other variables, G could not be calcu— lated in most cases due to no variation between uses in the quality of risk information. When G could not be calcu- lated, the quality of risk information tended to be zero. —163- Findings For EPA's Risk Ranking. One explanatory vari— able was used to predict differences in the quality of information between pesticides, as opposed to uses of a pesticide. That variable was the relative risk of each pesticide as measured by EPA's own risk ranking method. The intent of measuring the correlation between the EPA risk ranking and the quality of risk information was to test EPA Office of Pesticide Programs Chief Edwin Johnson's statement that the quality of the agency's risk-benefit analyses is determined by a pesticide's relative risk. Table 5.7 shows the results for this explanatory vari— able. There were some difficulties in averaging the quality of risk information across pesticides, mainly because risk categories were not consistent between pesticides. For example, gamma could not even be calculated for the ground applicator risk category, because several of the pesticides had more than one type of ground applications. Supporting tables for Table 5.7 can be found in Appendix B (Tables 37 through 44). The results were a mixed bag. There were five risk categories showing primarily positive gammas, and two show- ing primarily negative. Across all risk categories, 25 of 45 positive gammas were in the weakly positive quartile (.001 to .250). Very few gammas could not be calculated (13 of 78 total gammas). Seven of those 13 occurred in toxicity and the risk portion of each risk category because only one pesticide, Dimethoate, was considered to have a risk of mutagenicity -- therefore, there could be no variance in the . in? is. .3896 «as. 8:89“ gas. 3:898 .32 c.5896 is. 838..» .12 93896 .9339 A 33:. 8328 -164- , GOOHHOOO’H' n ' a n O . M 23.8 no :3» sun-Em n h n O n M M 023008. as. 2:308 no unis. ~86. 0:33.: .33-on . a 3838.. #38. .. M 0.0 0,0 .2 u .8 M 000000 A O 0 000000 OOOON o o OOOOO—IOO OOOOHo—c—a o OOOUDN o o OONOOOO—fl OVOONHOOO OOOONOO o OOOMDOOOO OOOONOO—I o OOHHOHOOO O dHOOOOOo-O o; 3 Sp. 92.. 3 Sn. 8a.. 3 3d. 8.... 3 H8. o 3 2a.- 8a... 3 8...- 8a.- 3 at..- as... 3 o4- .8003 35632 8 a 3.5: 00395 2.030.. .8833 can 0.3qu no 35 9.008 a 30:3 030523 5 acid: £02590 3»: I: undue 9. ocean-nu 38!»... 3'83 ~35: c. an 33, 838585 is. a... 33.3 888.. 1.» ...... 25.3. is. can. 5.38 .83-188 no Ella «.... .38 —l65- quality of information. fNua other five that could not be calculated under risk from accidents and spills represented average quality of information of zero across all pesti- cides. In short, Johnson's hypothesis is not supported. There could be several reasons for this. One is that he could be just plain wrong. ,Another could txa the method of testing his hypothesis or the data constraints in this research. A third possibility is that EPA does the best it can in ob- taining risk information, but it is forced to work under the technological constraints hampering all risk assessments. A final explanation could be that risk §£e_s_ drive EPA's in- formation-gathering process -- within the constraints of interest group pressure, a la Stigler and Peltzman. Johnson may be right about the internal workings of EPA, but he may be less than fully aware of the external constraints on agency operations. Summary; Correlation Between Explanatory Variables and Quality of Information on Risk. In general, the hypo- thesized relationships between the explanatory variables and the quality of risk information did not hold up well. In fact, some of the evidence even showed results opposite of what was expected. And in many cases, the information was uniformly bad. Some of the major reasons why these general results may have occurred include: / O ,/ 1 fi 6 6 -/ ,/ / Interest groups, {BECK as pesticide manufacturers and users, may not want better_r_i_s_l_<_ information. Therefore, they will not try to influence the in- formation gathering process, other than to try to sabotage it. The risk assessment methodology is often more art than science. This could be one cause of the poor risk information. The EPA may not have the necessary budget to obtain good data. In general, EPA only receives toxicity data from pesticide manufacturers. Exposure data are EPA's responsibility, and they can be very costly to obtain. Even if manufacturers do provide exposure data, EPA may discount the value of those data. Interest groups may prefer to allocate their scarce resources toward improving benefits information, in the hope that better information on a pesticide use's benefits will lead to less stringent regula- tions. The manufacturers and users may feel that they have a much better chance of making an impact (Hi the benefits side than on the risk side. The results outlined in Chapter 6 would seem to support this hypothesis. CHAPTER 6 RESULTS: QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON BENEFITS OF PESTICIDE USE The EPA relies heavily on professionals from USDA, state agencies, and land-grant universities in the preparation of the benefits analysis. This chapter explores the quality of the information contained in the benefits analyses, and provides some insight into the power of different groups to influence the quality of information. GENERAL OBSERVATIONS ON EPA'S BENEFITS ANALYSES Various groups provide input via the comment process and other informal mechanisms on the benefits of pesticide use. EPA often uses this input, especially when the groups are pesticide user groups. Several examples can be cited to illustrate this point. 131 the case of the pesticide Endrin, the agency stated in position documents that undefended uses of the pesticide were to be canceled -- the apparent assumption was that if a use was undefended, there must be no benefits from that particular use of the pesticide. This, of course, ignores what Peltzman, Stigler and others have worked so hard to point out -- that there are costs of using the political process. ~167- -l68- In the case of Chlorobenzilate, a similar attitude was present with the use of the pesticide on citrus fruit in Arizona. Although Arizona citrus growers face similar pest problems and growing conditions as growers in Texas, EPA initially canceled Chlorobenzilate use on Arizona citrus, while retaining its use, with restrictions, in Texas. EPA's reason for the Arizona decision, as reported in position document 2/3, was that there must be no benefits of use since Arizona growers did not respond to a USDA survey on the subject. Upon protest from USDA and the eventual re- ceipt of information from Arizona, EPA reconsidered and decided to allow restricted use of Chlorobenzilate in Arizona. It is possible that EPA was attempting to appease groups opposed to Chlorobenzilate by canceling the "use of least resistance" -- in this case, use by a small group of producers with potentially high costs of articulating preferences to EPA. Only when USDA played the role of political entrepreneur was the use of Chlorobenzilate on Arizona citrus salvaged. Another example of user impact on the regulatory process involves a small group of users of the nematocide DBCP with high per capita benefits of use and an already-existing political organization called the Pineapple Growers Associ- ation of Hawaii (PGAH). PGAH provided information on the risks and benefits of DBCP use on pineapple, which EPA used extensively in its risk-benefit analysis. While many uses of the pesticide were canceled, the use on pineapple was -l69- registered with restrictions. Of course, the registration may have been approved for reasons other than PGAH's dialog with EPA. This example not only illustrates the potential influence of a user group on the quality of information in a pesticide risk-benefit analysis, but it is also a fine example of EH1 already-organized interest group with access to the regulatory process. EPA simplifies its information search by bounding the problem and the variables to be measured (as pointed out in Chapter 3). For example, the economic impacts of pesticide cancellation on pesticide manufacturers are either excluded or only tmiefly touched upon ix! EPAHs benefits analysis. Total compliance with proposed restrictions is always assumed, and "expert opinions" are heavily relied upon as a source of data. Changes in prices of agricultural products and in related goods, resulting from pesticide regulation, as well as changes in prices of inputs other than the pest- icide, are often dismissed. As with risk analysis strategies, it is difficult to estimate the impact of these strategies on the accuracy of EPA's benefits information. The assumption of total com— pliance overstates the costs of pesticide regulation, but this may be compensated for by EPA's failure to quantify the effects of price changes. Also, EPA has a tendency to implicitly attribute all potential losses in benefits due to cancellation to pesticide users without acknowledging that consumers and pesticide manufacturers will absorb some of ~170- those losses. This overstates the benefits of pesticide use to user groups although it does not result in an overstate- ment of total benefits. Again, the internal structure of EPA's Office of Pesti- cide Programs sheds some light (”I the impacts included in EPA's Benefits Studies. The Benefits and Field Studies Division of OPP is responsible for the benefits analyses, and contains an Animal Sciences and Index Branch, a Plant Sciences Branch and an Economic Analysis Branch. Figure 6.1 shows what is ideally accounted for by each branch. THE QUALITY OF EPA'S BENEFITS INFORMATION Table 6.1 summarizes the quality of information obtained by EPA for its benefits analyses for the eight case study pesticides. The data for the two major benefits categories measuring changes in pest control costs and value of production were noticeably clustered around the lower end of the quality of information scale. Well over half of the variables were either ignored or only qualitatively mentioned. Another 35.9 percent of the variables were quantified on the basis of assumptions or, in most cases, expert opinions. Only 6.1 percent of the 773 pieces of data were based on some sort of study. It is obvious that EPA does not usually rely on or conduct studies on the benefits of pesticide use. The prices of goods for which the pesticides are an input were measured on a different scale than the other variables. Prices were ignored more than half of the time, -171- BFSD Branch Insect icides/ Herbicides/ Component Rodenticides Fungiches Current use analysis EPA registrations of RPARs ASIBa PSBb and alternatives Recommendations for use of ASIB PSB RPAR and alternatives Use of RPAR and alternatives EABC EAB Performance evaluation of RPAR and alternatives Pest infestation and damage ASIB PSB Comparative performance ASIB PSB evaluation Use impact analysis EAB EAB (projected change in use) Economic impact analysis Impact on production cost EAB EAB Impact on volume produced EAB EAB Impact on consumer prices EAB EAB Aggregated economic impact EAB EAB Limitations of analysis EAB EAB a Animal Sciences and Index Branch. b Plant Sciences Branch. Economic Analysis Branch. Source: Environmental Studies Book Committee on Prototype Explicit Analyses for Pesticides, Regulating Pesti- National Research Council, cides (Washington, D.C. 1966), p. 38. Figure 6.1 Components of Pesticide Benefit Analysis (for a given site) and Principal Organizational Respon— sibilities in the Office of Pesticide Programs -172- 536 use 5386 3.84 a 5.5 832. 5.33358 a banal-co uo 3&3 ammo; A fit. 833 .335358 A 53938 no 32390 38;... n 51. 32.3 .833353 e 83.8 8 e58 :63. .833356 m 8 o 8:8 :63. .9333; e 8 o .258 toes 5333.56 n 00 O 33 .2583an N 38..." n 3835.. 38332.8 a 33:3 8 e899 o 88 we 8:5 n ”.58 .36 02333 no 886 S .63.. 8 e83 .333358 a. 2.39532 53 £3.13 .. .88 .38 33:8,. 8 .3338 53 {said .. 3 o 33- 8 ...-B 533358 e 358.32 51. £33» s . . .3338 5a.. <23: n v.34.” «3 .338 3.98 .833353 n 335.: .83 .. . . . 33953:}. on»: 38¢ I 68% en also. £333.30 ~ 2.3.83? no <8: .. usgnsnsfi we :8 a .338 8a 3835.. 333323 a . 3.8:. 38s .. . .3338 no {one u . 2.2.8 a3 6883 e “.2388“qu «o .38 a 38. no 0 a” 2530: ac «mace-t 01.8 A 333...; 7 agent Saul-85 3388 no 33.8 no i a.» .38 . -173- ”abhomd . 883 a~mm.m~ «mmm.mv Heap? No a «2 . mam _ Hhm 303333.. no 380 I 85:98 - .385 338 I 30:9: 0% I 3085 38388 I 389: no 333333“. .. 808 35o 30 8% :0 Bug I 380 8383.6 .350 S 8:20 .. . 8383 no 358 ~23.33.35:..38 m 81> 5 «9.20 ”Boa .. 83838 we 83> .368 633838 N 5 856 82 .38 .. . 38 33:8 33; 83338 H S 0936 ~38. .. 330 ”83:8 38 080:3" o 5 8:98 80¢ you I. 8:362 quflmmIoo: 300m 33039 uguao: .3538. 83.88:: 3388 no 33.8 no Ella a.» .36 -l74- but when they were not ignored, they were generally based on some type of a study. However, variation of price with quality and/or supply of the good was rarely considered. Finally, several variables were measured on a 0-3 scale. These variables were either summary variables (changes in pest control costs, changes in value of production) or else they were poorly documented so that all that could really be said was that they were ignored, qualitatively measured or quantitatively measured. Once again, nearly half of these variables were ignored. Another 28.3 percent were only qualitatively mentioned. Only 22.3 percent of the 1459 pieces of data were quantified. CORRELATION BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND THE QUALITY OF INFORMATION ON BENEFITS This section of the Chapter examines the extent of correlations, as measured by gamma, between the hypothesized explanatory variables and the quality of information used by EPA to assess the benefits of the 86 uses of the eight pest- icides. There were 244 potential gammas for each explana- tory variable, but one of two results were found. If there was no variation in the quality of benefits information between all uses of a pesticide, gammas could not be calcu- lated. Otherwise, a gamma within the range of -l to +1 was calculated. Of the total 976 potential gammas for four explanatory variables, 274 of them could not be calculated. The following tables 6.2 through 6.5 are of the same format as tables 5.3 through 5.6. Each table represents a -175- summary of the correlations between one explanatory variable and the quality of EPA's benefits data. For each explana- tory variable one of the tables shows: 0 The numbers and values of the gamma coefficients that could be calculated for each of five benefits categories. 0 The quality of information within each of the five benefits categories when gamma coefficients could not be calculated (i.e., when there was no varia- tion in the quality of benefits data between uses of a pesticide). o The total potential numbers of gamma coefficients within each of the five benefits categories. 0» The number of pesticides for which one or more gamma coefficients could be calculated for each of the five benefits categories. Unless otherwise noted, the number is the total out of a possible eight pesticides. o The number of pesticides with primarily positive gammas, primarily negative gammas, and equal numbers of positive and negative gammas. The benefits data are delineated according to five bene- fits categories: changes in pest control costs, changes in value of production, other socioeconomic impacts, distrib- ution of impacts, and compliance costs. In the tables, they are arranged from left to right in decreasing order of importance in EPA's benefits analyses. ~176- The same measurement scale used in tables 5.3 through 5.6 was used to describe the values of the gammas that could be calculated for the quality of benefits data. That scale is: -1 to -.750 -.749 to -.500 -.499 to -.250 -.249 to O .001 to .250 .251 to .500 .501 to .750 .751 to 1 Also, as in tables 5.3 through 5.6, gammas that could not be calculated due to a lack of variation in quality of benefits data were designated with "--". The number in parentheses shows the quality of benefits information across all uses of a pesticide that could be measured for a particular explana— tory variable. The "total possible G” line is the sum of the gammas that could be calculated and those that could not. The lower half of each table depicts the number of pest- icides that showed positive, negative or ambiguous relation- ships between the explanatory variable and the quality of information for each of the five benefits categories. The figures show whether a large number of positive gammas in a benefits category reflect many positive gammas for one pesticide, or a positive trend for several pesticides. The -l77- latter would reflect the kind of correlation hypothesized for the explanatory variable and the quality of benefits information. Once again, Table 5.2 should be used to show the number of uses of each pesticide that could be measured for each of the four explanatory variables. Supporting tables for Tables 6.2 through 6.5 can be found in Appendix 8 (Tables 45 through 67). Findings for Value of Pesticide Use to Manufacturers. The intent of using the value of a particular pesticide use to the manufacturers as an explanatory variable was to proxy the likelihood of manufacturers to get involved in the regulatory process, due to their potential losses from regulation (M5 the pesticide use. The hypothesis was that the quality of information would improve as the value of a pesticide use to the manufacturers increased. The results shown in Table 6.2 seem to support this hypothesis. For all of the benefits categories except "compliance costs," a majority of the gammas could be cal- culated. When there was no variation in the quality of benefits information and G could not be calculated, the predominant quality of information ranged from three (expert opinion) for the major category of "changes in pest control costs" to zero (ignored) for the minor categories of "other socioeconomic impacts" and "distribution of impacts." Most pesticides for which gamma could be calculated showed predominantly positive gamma coefficients across all -l78- aunt:su-qwcauunumluuuqunwocumaununuuum-ucuuum-m-a» hnhauu “kid 6 QMNIQGI manage- Chnuiuhu cunninum- «hrhdr' ouuuuun uqmwu. «Pumahn bmuulnuu «luau .100 a .07” -07. b .0” -0” b .03 .0” :0 0 .miu.ao .aiu.wo .QID.”O .731 a 10° Rauuuoou BOOQUUOQ 0P09HNNU Conunwoa ”0000000 t -(fl —Wfl —40 -19 -M) —4M -Wfl —(U -wm -(fl anuoUoo N000~l00000 oUwou ocoow OUMON u G 8 bulb-who flrHM$GGMd boauuud mama-nu pdunch «mad-nu mpunch ‘mmqnnnnnn otpuuns mpdnch unnotuuuu- 3E -l79- five risk categories. Only three pesticides ever showed primarily negative or equal numbers of positive and negative gammas: Endrin, Amitraz and Silvex. For Endrin, only 3 (of a possible 11) uses could be measured according to value to manufacturer. Amitraz and Silvex each had only two measur— able uses. 80 all of the pesticides with larger numbers of measurable uses, including Dimethoate and DBCP with 24 and 17 measurable uses respectively, showed primarily positive gammas across all five benefit categories. If these results occurred because pesticide manufac— turers are able 1x) influence the regulatory process, then manufacturers must be convinced that improving benefits information will help them achieve more favorable regulatory outcomes for high-value uses of a pesticide. But there could be other reasons for the correlation between value to manufacturers and quality of benefits information. One is that benefits information is easy to obtain, relative to risk information, and so EPA chooses to expend its limited resources on good benefits information for higher-value uses. This does not seem likely if EPA is serving as a political entrepreneur for risk-bearers: in that case, the agency would probably want to avoid extensive information on benefits. However, USDA's control over the benefits analy- ses may have some impact on what EPA would like to see. A second alternative explanation for the positive correlation is that better benefits information may already be developed and available for the higher-value uses. -180- Findings for Percent of Crop Treated. The explanatory variable "percent of crop treated” was intended to proxy the number of users of a pesticide that would be affected by a regulatory action. The hypothesis was that the quality of benfits information would improve as the number of users increased, because political entrepreneurs (namely, USDA and user groups) would become more active in the process if a greater proportion of their constituencies were affected. Table 6.3 shows the results of the empirical testing of this hypothesis. The results support the hypothesis except in the ”other socioeconomic impacts” benefits category. In that category, there are equal numbers of positive and nega- tive gammas, and equal numbers of pesticides with primarily positive and primarily negative gammas. For all five of the benefits categories, the pesticides with primarily negative Gs and equal numbers of positive and negative Gs range from Dimethoate (20 measurable uses) to 2,4,5-T and Amitraz (2 measurable uses). They are not exclusively the two and three measurable use-pesticides, as is the case for the value of use to manufacturers explanatory variable. Once again, a majority of the possible gammas can be calculated in all benefits categories except for the "com- pliance costs” category. And once again, the quality of information ranges from zero to three when gamma cannot be calculated. The same types of alternative explanations described in the last section could explain the correlation for this -181- tial-6.3 mummummuqamaumuwumm Wotan-(mummmmmum) Value of m in but any. in ma- Otlur acto- Distribution W a (lateral m of mucus We tweets of nect- mots 4.0 a -.750 4 (4) 9 (9) 2 (2) 2 (2) o -.749 to -.300 0 (O) 0 (0) 1 (1) 1 (l) o «20 to o 1 (1) 2 (2) 4 (4) 1 (1) 0 .ml to .250 5 (4) 14 (11) J, (2) 4 (4) l .251 to .300 10 (14) 9 (13) 4 (4) _ 4 (4) o .301 to .7” I (6) 5 (5) 2 (2) 2 (1) O .731 to 1.0 16 (15) 19 (13) 4 (4) 6 (7) 1 m1 6 9 22 23 3 - (a) o - (7) o — (6) o - (5) o o - (4) o o - (3) 1,4 9 2 2 2 - (2) 0 O 0 0 0 - (1) 1 2 2 4 4 - (O) 1 4 14 ll 3 - (7) 10 2 O O 0 M 26 17 13 17 9 m1 mm. 6 72 an 0 0 12 line: of nautical-o fa.- was: 6 and b- alcuhud a a 7 8 2 of a pan. 6 with My ‘ punitiv- 6'1 5 6 3 s l with My ”use 0'. 1 2 3 2 O with «3.1 M of positive I ”the 6's 2 0 1 1 l -182- explanatory variable. First, the hypothesized relationship could be true. Second, EPA (or USDA) may decide on its own to pursue good information for those uses with a high pro- portion of users. Third, better benefits information may already be available for the high percentage uses. Findings for Annual Per Acre User Losses. The "annual per acre user losses” explanatory variable was intended to be an approximate measure of per capita user losses. The hypothesized relationship is that the quality of benefits information will improve as per capita losses increase, because individual users will have more at stake and will therefore attempt to influence the regulatory process. Table 6.4 summarizes the empirical results. The results are similar to those in Table 6.2 for the value of a pesti— cide use to manufacturers, but they are even more positive in the two major benefits categories, "changes in pest control costs” and "changes in value of production.” A majority of the Gs that can be calculated are positive for all five categories, and most of those are .251 or greater. In addition, most of the pesticides for which one or more gammas can be calculated show primarily positive gammas across all benefits categories. When pesticides do show primarily negative or equal numbers of positive and negative gammas, they usually either have few measurable uses or few measurable gammas, or both. As for the previous two explanatory variables, a major- ity of the possible gammas cannot be calculated for "compli- ance costs.” Also, most gammas can't be calculated for -183- ”1.6.4 mamumawmumuuum uda—(med-nummugu) Valu- ot Ouaga- 1n but any. in m Other Socio- cm W a m m at We: We m of Inact- Oust- -1.0 to -.750 2 (2) 7 (7) 2 (1) 1 (1) o (0) -.249 to O 1 (O) 3 (2) 4 (4) 4 (5) 0 (1) .001 to .250 5 (2) 9 (6) 2 (2) 2 (2) o (0) .251 no .500 9 (11) 15 (14) 5 (5) 2 (3) 1 (0) .301 to .750 7 (11) 3 (17) 1 (2) 3 (3) 1 (O) .751 to 1.0 24 (21) 17 (14) 8 (7) 6 (5) 1 (1) M 43 61 23 19 3 - (I) - (7) — (6) - (5) 1 1 -- (4) o o — (3) 14 9 2 2 y 2 - (2) 0 0 0 0 o - (1) o 3 2 a 4 - (O) 1 2 13 11 3 - (7) a 4 o 0 0 M 24 19 17 21 9 m1 W G 72 an 40 0 12 Moth-tidal- «mew be amulet-d 8 a 7 7 2 of a pan. 6 with My positive 0': 6 6 5 5 1 with My ”tive 6'. 1- 2 2 0 O with «:11 m of positive I uptic- 6'. l o 0 2 1 -184- ”distribution of impacts." The quality of information when gamma cannot be calculated ranges from zero (ignored) to five (quantitative point estimate based on a study or pub- lished data). The fact that there was a strong positive correlation between the proxy for per capita user losses and the quality of benefits information lends credence to the Stigler/ Peltzman theory that per capita economic impacts motivate individuals to organize in an effort to affect regulatory outcomes. Although the existence of the positive correla- tion does not prove that (or any of the other) hypothesis, it certainly supports the theory. Findings for Annual Total User Losses. The last vari- able used to explain variation between uses of a single pesticide was ”annual total user losses.” This variable was meant to describe the aggregate annual losses for all users, as compared to the "per acre user losses" variable intended to capture individual user losses. The relationship between total user losses and quality of information was expected to be a positive one, reflecting the expected participation of pesticide users (or their political entrepreneurs) in the regulatory process as potential economic losses increase. Table 6.5 shows that, again, most gammas could be calcu- lated except for compliance costs and distribution of impacts. When gamma could not be calculated, the quality of information ranged from zero to five. In the two major categories, changes in pest control costs and changes in -185- Tam-6.5 mammmwamamummmw. mac-(mmpmmmmmtm) m ot Gunp- in that M in Nut 0th..- ado- W W G W m of Wm We met. of m m «70 to -.300 0 (O) O (O) 1 1 (1) o -.249 to o 0 (O) 2 (2) 4 3 (3) 0 .m1 to .250 4 (3) 4 (5) 2 1 (2) o .251 to .300 9 (12) 13 (14) 5 3 (5) 1 .501 to .750 6 (5) 1O (7) 3 4 (1) o .751 to 1.0 21 (22) , 16 (19) 4 5 (5) 2 amen 44 56 21 16 3 - (6) O - (7) O - (6) o - (5) 1 1 - (4) o o - (3) 18 12 3 3 2 - (2) o o o o o — (1) o 3 3 a 4 - (O) 1 4 13 11 3 - (7) a 4 o o 0 am 23 24 19 22 9 total loam. 6 72 so ' 40 4o 12 Moth-tida- tormdlcomld be clan-ted 8 6 7 7 2 of a " ”a 6 with may positive G'- 6 6 4 5 2 with print-117 ”tive 6's 0 2 1 1 o with 4931 m of positive 4 ”tin 6's 2 O 2 1 O -186- value of production, the quality of information was usually three (expert opinion) or better when gamma could not be calculated due to ru> variation between uses. But in the three minor categories, the quality of information was usually zero (ignored) or one (qualitative measurement). The results for gammas that could be calculated were similar to those for per acre user losses in Table 6.4. Gammas were usually positive for all five benefits cate- gories, and most pesticides showed primarily positive gammas. At first blush, the correlation summarized in Table 6.4 for per acre user losses appears to be stronger. But when one looks at the two major benefits categories, which far outweigh the three minor categories in terms of EPA's time and the importance of the information to the regulatory process, the annual total user losses variable appears to have slightly greater explanatory power. The pesticides with primarily negative gammas and equal numbers of positive and negative gammas in the two major benefits categories were Amitraz and 2,4,5-T, both of which had only two measur- able uses for annual total user losses. This result does rMM: quite match the Stigler/Peltzman theory that per capita economic stake determines attempts to influence the regulatory process. But one possible explan— ation for the slightly stronger explanatory power of aggregate user losses is that USDA and already-existing user groups are political entrepreneurs for pesticide users. These political entrepreneurs may be more sensitized to —l87- react to an aggregate figure reflecting losses to all users, rather than data on individual impacts. Findings for EPA's Risk Ranking. Once again, Edwin Johnson's statement that the risk of a pesticide drives the regulatory process was tested. In order to test the hypo— thesis, EPA's risk ranking for each pesticide was used as the explanatory variable. The quality of benefits informa- tion for a pesticide was measured by averaging the in- formation quality across all uses of the pesticide. The results of this test can be found in Table 6.6. Averaging the quality of information data across uses was easier for benefits than for risk, so the benefits results are probably somewhat more reliable. Supporting tables for Table 6.6 can be found in Appendix B (Tables 69 through 73). To put it simply, there was absolutely no indication the Johnson statement holds true for benefits information. All of the possible gammas could be calculated, and most of them were negative. The negative gammas were clustered around the two least negative ranges for gamma (-.249 to 0 and —.499 to -.250). None of tflua five benefits categories showed primarily positive gammas - (flue two major categories were very pre- dominantly negative and the three minor categories showed equal numbers of positive and negative gammas. This is a very interesting result. It makes sense that Johnson's statement would test out (1) be true, given the strong correlations already' shown between interest group -188- Table 6.6 Sm of Oorrelatione between @A'e Peeticide Riel: mm and the Average Quality of Benefite Inter-tion Huber of. Galilee Changee Charge in Other in Peat Value of Socioeconaic Distribution Clo-pliance Value of G Control Ooeta Production Igcte of 353:2: Ooete -1.0 to -.750 o o o ' o o -.749 to -.5(X) 1 3 O 1 O -.499 to -.250 5 ' 3 1 o 1 -.249 to O 4 3 2 2 2 O .001 to .250 O 2 0 1 O .251 to .500 O 0 .‘ O” 0 1 .501 to .750 O O 2 O 0 .751 to 1.0 O O O 1 O -—-- O O O 0 O ' mm Poeeible o 9 - 10 5 , s ' 2 Primary Sign of Gal—a . poeitive negative at at equal mater of positive and j _ negative at x x —189- "propensity to participate" and the quality of benefits information. But why the negative results for the two major risk categories? Could it be that interest groups are pragmatic, and decide not to put as much pressure on EPA's benefits analyses when pesticide risk is high? Participation in the regulatory process can be costly, so it would be wise of the interest groups (and their political entrepreneurs) to save their scarce political and economic resources for pesticide regulatory processes where they think they can win. Findings for All of the Explanatory Variables and EPA's Decisions on Pesticide Registration. The ultimate goal for interest groups trying to affect the regulatory process is obtainimg a favorable pesticide registration decision from the EPA. Table 6.7 summarizes the correlation between EPA decisions and the four variables used to explain variation between EESE of a pesticide. A supporting table for Table 6.7 is found in Appendix B (Table 68). The results bode well for the interest groups and ill for the EPA. Decisions varied between measurable uses for only four of the eight pesticides, so the "decision-explanatory vari— able" gamma could only be calculated for those four (DBCP, Amitraz, Endrin, Chlorobenzilate). When decisions did not vary, all uses were registered with restricted use or sent to administrative hearings. When gamma could be calculated, it was virtually always positive, indicating a positive relationship between the -l90- Table 6.7 Su-ry of Correlations between EPA Pesticide Registration Decisions and Four Explanatory Variables Muster of Games (“shore in parentheses denote lower range Gs) Explanatory Variable: Value of Use to Percent Annual per Acre Annual mm Value of Gene Manufacturers Crop Treated User Losses User Losses -1.0 to -.750 o o (0) o (0) o -.749 to -.500 o o (0) o (0) o -.499 to -.250 o o (0) o (a) o -.249 to o 1 1 (o) o (0) 1 .001 to .250 o o (0) o (0) o .251 to .500 1 ‘ o (15 1 (2) o .501 to .750 o 1 (1) 2 (1) 1 .751 to 1.0 2 2 (2) 1 (1) 2 —— 4 4 (4), 4 (4) 4 Total Possible G 8 8 8 8 Meter of haticides (mumpnntheaesdemtelomrrangeGe) for which 6 oould A be calculated 4 4 (4) 4 4 with positive 6 3 3 (4) 4 3 with negative 6 1 1(0) 0 o with G . 0 O O (O) O 1 -l9l- four explanatory variables and EPA decisions. For example, the data show that as the value of a pesticide use to the manufacturers increases, EPA is more likely to fully regis- ter that use in three of the four pesticides for which gamma could be calculated. The apparent success of pesticide manufacturers and users in influencing EPA's decisions is further emphasized by the gamma calculated to show the correlation between EPA's pesticide risk rankings and the average decisions made for each pesticide. That gamma was calculated to be -.368, indicating that the more risky pesticides, determined by EPA's own standards, are not the most regulated pesticides. Summary: Correlation Between Explanatory Variables and Quality of Information on Benefits. The differences between the empirical results for risk and benefit information are like night and day. For some reason, the empirical results 1x1 this reseach indicate that pesticide umnufacturers and users seem far better able (or willing) to affect EPA's benefits analyses than its risk analyses. Some of the reasons for this disparity in results might include: o Pesticide users and manufacturers want risk infor- mation to remain as incomplete and vague as pos- sible, because they do not think they will be able to rebut EPA's preliminary risk findings. 0 EPA serves as a political entrepreneur for risk bearers, and so has managed to insulate itself from user and manufacturer pressure to improve exposure —l92- and risk data for the most important use of a pesticide. o Pesticide users and manufacturers have decided to channel their limited political and financial resources toward the benefits side of the equation, because they feel that they can accomplish more by improving benefits information. o USDA (and perhaps some well-organized user and manufacturer groups) serves as a: political entre- preneur for pesticide users, and possibly manufac- turers. Since USDA seems to oversee the benefits analysis, it channels RPAR resources into good benefits data for the most important pesticide uses. The empirical results also indicate that EPA's pesticide risk ranking does an ambiguous job of explaining the varia- tion in the quality of risk data between pesticides, and a terrible job of explaining the variation in the quality of benefits data. Why is this so, when Edwin Johnson so con- fidently claims that risk drives the information gathering process? Again, there are several possibilities. Johnson may simply be wrong. Or perhaps some flaw in the empirical work has resulted in arguable findings. A third possibility is that Johnson perceives that risk drives the process from his perch within the agency. But maybe EPA's pesticide reg- ulation is really driven by external constraints including interest group pressure, and the process is only driven by -l93- risk within those constraints. In the case of benefits, the USDA-pesticide user liaison may be so powerful that it overshadows EPA's internal constraints. In summary, the strong correlation between the explana- tory variables and the quality of benefits information does not necessarily prove that interest groups affect EPA's information search. during pesticide regulation. But the empirical results certainly lend a good deal of support to various theories of interest group power. CHAPTER 7 CONCLUSIONS OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH Zhi a broad sense, this research was an effort to gain some insight into EPA's regulation of pesticides. The specific objective, as noted in Chapter 1, was to provide systematic, empirical information about EPA's information- gathering activities ixx the Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration (RPAR) process. The quality of EPA's risk and benefit information was empirically described, and hypo- theses on interest group pressure were tested. To briefly review the structure of this thesis, theories of regulatory decision making and a conceptualization of pesticide risks anui benefits were described in Chapters 2 and 3. In Chapter 4, the methodology for the empirical work was outlined. Scales were developed to depict the quality of various pieces of risk and benefit information for each use of each pesticide. EPA documents were used to measure the quality of information variables, which served as the dependent variables in the research. Explanatory variables were also quantified from EPA documents. Four of the ex— planatory variables measured the incentive for pesticide users or manufacturers to become involved in the regulation of a pesticide use: the fifth ranked the eight case study -l94- ~195- pesticides according to EPA's own determination of risk in an effort to explain differences in the quality of informa— tion between pesticides. Thus, correlations between the four "interest group” explanatory variables and quality of information were measured for each pesticide, while the EPA risk ranking variable was used to explain variation across all of the pesticides. SUMMARY OF RESULTS The results of the empirical work can be found in Chap- ters S and 6. There were four major findings: 0 All five explanatory variables showed mixed results when correlated with the quality of risk informa- tion. The variables could not be considered to be highly correlated with the quality of risk infor- mation in either a positive or a negative way. 0 The four "interest group" variables (value of pesticide to manufacturers, percent of crOp treated, per acre user losses, and total user losses) showed positive correlations with the quality of benefits information. The strongest showings came from the per acre user losses and total user losses variables, intended to proxy the per capita losses and industry-wide losses from pesticide cancellation. The EPA pesticide risk ranking variable showed positive and negative correlations with the quality of benefits infor- mation, so the relationships could not be deter- mined. -l96— EPA failed to measure or even mention many of the risk and benefits variables. When risk data were quantified, the sources tended to be assumptions, expert opinions, or studies of other pesticides instead of studies of the pesticide in question. For benefits data, theme was a great reliance on expert opinions and assumptions. EPA usually quantified the major risk and benefit categories, such as consumer and ground applicator exposure and risk, changes in pest control costs, and changes in value of production. But the remaining categories were generally ignored or only qualitatively men— tioned. Overall, EPA's information was not good and risk information was poorer than benefits information. It appears that interested parties were able to affect EPA's decisions. The four "interest group" variables did a good job of explaining EPA's de- cisions. As the economic stake of users and manu- facturers for a particular pesticide use increased, so did the likelihood of an EPA decision to reg- ister or conditionally register that use. It seems that pesticide users and manufacturers were able to obtain decisions that minimized their losses, possibly at the expense of risk bearers (especially given that a negative correlation exists between stringency of decisions and EPA's pesticide risk rankings.) -l97- ANALYSIS OF RESULTS Value Judgments in Pesticide Regulation. There are many assumptions made, but not highlighted, in EPA's risk-benefit analysis. Some of these value judgments were carried over into this research in order to analyze EPA's activities. The first that comes to mind is the definition of benefits, costs (subtracted from benefits to obtain net benefits) and risk. EPA's definition of these parameters affects the issues addressed, how they are measured, and ultimately, how those issues are resolved. But perhaps more importantly, this definition of net benefits and risk assumes a particu- lar distribution of property rights. It is usually the status quo distribution of rights that is assumed by EPA as a gauge to measure net benefits and risk, and this assumes that the status quo is the best set of rights. Other value judgments used by EPA in its analysis in- clude assumptions necessary 1x3 quantify human risk and to judge the acceptability of that risk. As Wessel (1980) suggests, science itself is valueless, but the use of science requires value judgments. On the net benefits side, EPA makes a value judgment as soon as it aggregates user losses from pesticide regulation (or disaggregates into per acre user losses). Assuming that additional dollars are of equal value to all pesticide users or that average per acre losses even begin to reflect indi- vidual differences makes the analysis far less predictive of -l98- real human impacts. In addition, EPA often fails to con- sider the value or distribution of certain economic impacts. These value judgments are necessary for EPA to simplify its analyses, or for technical reasons. However, the fail- ure to acknowledge the assumptions can be misleading to participants in and students of the agency's regulatory process. Correlation Between Variables. One of the most striking results in the empirical work was the lack of correlation between the "interest group" explanatory variables and the quality of risk information, and the strong correlation of the variables with the quality of benefits information. At first glance, the benefits results are consistent with the hypothesized relationships, but the risk results are not. However, when considering the characteristics of EPA's regulatory process, the risk results may not seem so incon- sistent after all. 'The EPA is largely responsible for the preparation of the risk analysis. Although theme is a great deal of re- liance (N1 outside research to estimate exposure and toxi- city, it is still up to the EPA to choose which information to use and how to compile it into a risk analysis. A dif- ferent group of players has responsibility for the benefits analyses. USDA and land-grant university specialists team up with EPA economists to obtain the data for the prelim- inary benefits analyses. USDA seems to have primary responsibility for the analyses, which end up as fairly -199- polished USDA publications. For the case study pesticides for which they were pmblished, the benefits analyses were used virtually verbatim in EPA's final position documents. One of the theorists cited in Chapter 2, James Q. Wilson, refers to the participation of "political entre- preneurs" in the regulatory process. EPA appeared to assume this role in representing risk bearers for the eight case- study pesticides. Because of this agency role, EPA was expected to have some control over the amount and quality of risk data. The results seem to show this by reflecting no relationship between pesticide users' and manufacturers' incentives and the quality of risk information. Another possible explanation for the risk results is that the hypotheses may not have accurately reflected the relationship between better risk information and regulatory outcomes favorable to pesticide users and manufacturers. In fact, manufacturers and users may have felt that better information would be harder to challenge, and would lead to greater restrictions on pesticide use. The theories and hypotheses in Chapter 2 seemed to adequately explain the quality of benefits information. In fact, the relationships between per acre user losses and total user losses and the quality of benefits data may have been especially strong because the USDA served as a politi- cal entrepreneur for pesticide users. USDA and state agri- cultural experts provided most of the benefits information, and there is no doubt that their constituencies were made Up -200- of pesticide users. And EPA's allegiance to pesticide users seemed to decline with the quality of benefits information, as was demonstrated for Arizona citrus growers using Chloro- benzilate and the minor Endrin uses. Thus, there was a real incentive for pesticide users and their political entre- preneurs to provide good benefits information. The fact that EPA's pesticide risk ranking did not correlate positively with the average quality of risk and benefit information does not conflict with the hypotheses at all -- it simply suggests that EPA does not have complete control over the regulatory process. In fact, based on the results for the other four explanatory variables, it appears that pesticide users and manufacturers have greater control over the benefits information. The quality of risk informa- tion did show a slightly greater correlation with EPA's risk ranking than the benefits information, which indicates that EPA is better able to influence risk information. Finally, there was a strong positive correlation between the four ”interest group” explanatory variables and EPA's pesticide registration decisions, meaning that a pesticide use was more likely to be fully registered as its importance to manufacturers and users increased. But for the EPA pesticide risk ranking variable, EPA restrictions increased as risk decreased. This suggests that it is pesticide users and manufacturers who determine regulatory outcomes. EPA may be able to influence the quality of risk information to a very small degree, but the quality of benefits information -201- appears to be influenced by interest group politics. More importantly, so do pesticide decisions, which are the reg- ulatory bottom line. EPA: Vote-Maximizer or Budget-Maximizer? In Chapter 2, there were several hypotheses on the expected differences in results if EPA was a vote-maximizing or budget-maximizing agency. This section addresses those hypotheses. Predicted results for vote-maximizing agency. 1. Does costly information found in EPA's position documents support powerful groups? The risk information obtained by EPA did not appear to support pesticide users or manufacturers who are most likely the politically powerful groups. On the other hand, benefits information did appear to support those groups. However, since EPA prepared the risk analysis but not the benefits analysis, the answer to this question must be no, contrary to what would be expected if EPA were a vote-maximizing agency. 2. Did EPA's assumptions favor powerful groups? In general, the answer would again have to be no. Risk assump- tions tended to be worst cases, which certainly do not favor pesticide manufacturers and users. When benefits data were unknown, the impacts were usually ignored, resulting in lower benefits estimates. There were some notable excep- tions: the failure to account for dietary exposure in most non-consumer risk categories, and assumptions of total -202- compliance with proposed regulations. But in most cases, the assumptions did not favor the powerful groups. 3. Was there some information favoring Opposing groups? Although we would expect otherwise if EPA was a vote-maximizer, risk information. almost always seemed to favor risk-bearers. Risk bearers would not be expected to be powerful because of uncertainty of risk and high organi- zation costs, yet EPA ignored most toxicity and exposure information reflecting lower risk. 4. Were there assumptions or costly information favor- ing opposing groups? Again, the answer is yes, even though the vote-maximizing theories would suggest otherwise. EPA often made assumptions favoring risk bearers. Examples included using the one-hit model to determine risk and assumptions of tolerance levels when residues in food could not be found. Based on the answers to these four questions, it would be hard to claim that EPA maximized votes during its infor- mation search. However, the final pesticide registration decisions may have been a different story, since they seemed to favor the powerful groups. Predicted results for budget-maximizing agency. 1. Did EPA challenge information from powerful groups? EPA definitely expended a great deal of energy and resources in challenging pesticide manufacturers' risk rebuttal infor- mation. On the other hand, EPA did not generally challenge information showing extensive benefits of pesticide use. -203- 2. Did EPA's assumptions favor its role in regulating pesticides? Certainly some of the risk assumptions, such as assuming maximum allowable residues in food crops and using conservative "one-hit" risk models, resulted in higher risk estimates and a stronger role for EPA in pesticide regula- tion. EPA's own rules in triggering and implementing the RPAR process also seemed to protect that role, requiring toxicity (but not exposure) information to initiate the process, challenging manufacturer's toxicity data, and requiring manufacturer benefits of pesticide use to be ignored. 3. Did EPA expend resources to obtain information to protect its role? In general, EPA did not conduct its own studies -- the agency usually relied on risk data from government or academic studies or pesticide manufacturers, exposure data from studies of other pesticides, and benefits data from USDA. However, EPA definitely spent a lot of time and money (Hi the RPAR process, which is structured to strengthen EPA's role in pesticide regulation. 4. Did EPA force powerful groups to provide pro-EPA information or make it costly for them to provide anti-EPA information? The great bulk of the toxicity data, which incriminated the pesticide and triggered the RPAR process, was provided by pesticide manufacturers so that they could register a chemical. Information to dispel preliminary risk findings was costly for manufacturers because it had to be —204- provided in the adversarial rebuttal process. And informa- tion on the benefits of pesticides to manufacturers was almost infinitely costly since it could not be considered in the RPAR process. However, information on benefits to pesticide users appeared to be relatively easy to inject into the RPAR process, in spite of the fact that this type of information challenged stringent pesticide regulations. Again, this could have been a result of EPA's lack of con- trol over the benefits analyses. These four indicators suggest that EPA might have been a budget-maximizing agency during the information gathering stage of the RPAR process. The regulatory program appeared to be structured in a way that supported a role for EPA in pesticide regulation. Summary: EPA Incentives and Recommendations to Achieve Change. If budget maximization is (”KB of the goals that drives EPA's regulation of pesticides, operating within the constraints of limited agency resources is certainly another. Knowledge of these two agency goals, and of the impact of pesticide producers, users and risk-bearers on the attainment of these goals, can help in designing the regu- latory program to achieve different results. If EPA strives to obtain better information for higher- risk pesticides, as Edwin Johnson intimates, then the agency should look at mechanisms to improve risk information (if that information shows higher risk) and ways of increasing the relative power of risk-bearing groups. -205- Since EPA's constituency for purposes of justifying its budget requests is probably risk-bearing groups, the goal of budget maximization is consistent with dedicating more resources to high-risk pesticides. This is evidenced by the answers to the questions in the previous section. The problem is not EPA's intentions: it is the financial andw political constraints (ME regulatory life. Changing those constraints is not easy. It would involve attempts to obtain more funding for toxicity and exposure studies con- ducted within the EPA or by another agency. Alternatively, existing law could be amended to require pesticide manufac-: turers to provide more data. Increasing the relative power of risk-bearing groups could take the form of reducing the organization costs of such groups (i.e., subsidizing and encouraging the formation of groups) and reducing the costs of articulating risk- bearer preferences 1J1 the regulatory process (e.g., sur- veying risk-bearers, collecting better exposure data, hold- ing public hearings in areas where the pesticide is heavily used). Another way to increase the relative power of risk- bearers is to decrease the power of adversarial groups, such as pesticide manufacturers and users. USDA is doubtless the primary voice for pesticide users, and it appears that this role prevents EPA from achieving more stringent regulation of higher-risk pesticides. As a result, EPA could re- evaluate its relationship with USDA. In general, reducing opportunities to voice concerns will decrease the political clout of pesticide users and manufacturers. -206— THE ROLE OF INFORMATION: IMPLICATIONS FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS The bottom line for participants in the RPAR process is their impact on the decision and ultimate outcome of the process. Given that pesticide users and manufacturers apparently affect the quality of benefits information and, to a lesser extent, risk information, how does this trans- late into an impact on decisions? There are a couple of general statements that can be made about EPA's pesticide decisions. Once an RPAR has been issued, EPA is unlikely to fully register a product, because a decision outcome is needed which justifies the time and resources expended (Hi the decision-making process. Also, even the best information does not point to a clear decision for EPA. The risk of pesticide use is too uncertain for a calculation of the net benefits of alternative policies. Even if net benefits could be calculated, there is no reason to believe that EPA would find the answer, or the assump- tions on which it is based, politically acceptable. It was pointed out in Chapter 2 that EPA may have goals other than maximizing some normative measure of net social welfare. Given these two $64,350 Silvex Rangeland $750,000 Rice $11 [ 000 Apples ? Noncrop Uses ? Pears ? Prunes ? Sugarcane ? 2,4,5-T Rangeland $6,750,000 Noncrop Uses $800,000 Amitraz Pears $3,047,414 Apples $1,129,480 Chlorobenzilate Florida Citrus $3,220,000 Texas Citrus $406,000 Cotton $212,550 California Citrus $30,000 Arizona Citrus $24,000 Other "Little Use” (assigned value of $100) Fruits/Nuts ? Endrin Small Grains $1,380,000 Orchards $152,800 Cotton $149,910 Alfalfa ? Bird Perches ? Conifer Seeds ? Ornamentals ? Sugarcane ? Tree Paint ? Vegetable Seeds ? watermelon Seeds ? -217- DBCP Dimethoate -218- Soybeans Grapes Almonds vegetables/MeIons/Strawberries Peanuts Cotton Peaches/Nectarines Citrus Commercial Turf Plums Pineapple Home Lawns Other Berries Strawberry Nursery Stock Home Gardens Bananas Apricots, Cherries, Figs Ornamentals Sorghum Citrus Corn Cotton Tomatoes (Fresh) Dry Beans Alfalfa Grapes Livestock Premises Tomatoes (Process) Pecans Snap Beans (Fresh) Apples Snap Beans (Process) Safflower Lettuce Soybeans Brocolli Tobacco Citrus Blackfly Forest Seed Orchards Peppers Wheat Pears Ornamentals Turnips Swiss Chard Cabbage $8,293,260 $3,200,000 $2,289,390 $2,238,720 $2,140,650 $1,782,000 $1,203,180 $801,040 $363,000 $302,840 $250,660 < $134,000 $61,640 $10,720 < $31 350 "Negligible" (assigned value of $100) "Negligible" (assigned value of $100) ? $2,831,370 $2,067,768 $1,920,000 $1,690,648 $1,323,576 $1,081,404 $627,750 $617,014 $552,552 $544,050 $226,533 $198,090 $162,000 $151,258 $105,507 $71,982 $51,000 $47,988 $3,648 < $3,203 $1,698 1 $837 "Minor Use" (assigned value of $100) "Negligible use" (assigned value of $100) ‘0'0'0‘0 -219- Table A2. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Annual Total User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation Pesticide Pronamide 2,4,5—T Silvex Amitraz Chlorobenzilate Endrin 922 Lettuce (Salinas) Lettuce (Maria) Alfalfa Lettuce (Imperial) Lettuce (Other CA) Lettuce (AZ) Berries Ornamentals Turf Sugarbeet Seed Rangeland Rice Noncrop Areas Sugarcane Prunes Apples Rangeland Rice Noncrop Uses Pears Pears Apples Florida Citrus California Citrus Texas Citrus Cotton Fruits & Nuts Arizona Citrus Other Small Grains (Major Uses) Orchards Conifer Seeds Cotton Sugarcane Alfalfa Ornamentals Watermelon Seeds Other Vegetable Seeds Tree Paint Bird Perches Small Grains (Minor Uses) Total Annual User Lossfi $10,097,068 $2,429,724 $2,333,775 $1,305,390 $784,1CK) 455,655 ‘0'00000 $16,406, 000 515171000 ? $3,800,00 to $10,100,000 $1,800,000 $1,000,000 "Small" (assigned value of $100) "Not Significant" (assigned value of $100) "Not Significant" (assigned value of $100) ? $8,271,000 $-410,07O $27,177,600 $2,280,200 $240,400 §_$69,000 ? ? $14,700,000 to 15,400,000 $2,645,000 to 513361000 $3,000,000 $717,850 $4,600 ~ 0 ~ DBCP Dimethoate -220- Peaches/Nectarines Soybeans Grapes Vegetables/Melons/Strawberries Citrus Almonds Peanuts Pineapple Commercial Turf Strawberry Nursery Stock Plums Home Lawns Cotton Other Berries Apricots, Figs, Etc. Bananas Home Gardens Ornamentals Grapes Corn Tomatoes (Fresh) Snap Beans (Fresh) Dry Beans Cotton Alfalfa Brocolli Pecans Citrus Citrus Blackfly Snap Beans (Process) Apples Safflower Livestock Premises Tobacco Peppers Lettuce Wheat Pears Forest Seed Orchards Soybeans Tomatoes (Process) Sorghum Cabbage Swiss Chard Turnips Ornamentals $26,890,000 $21,670,000 $14,500,000 $8,950,000 $8,834,000 $6,800,000 $6,200,000 $2,200,000 to $5,600,000 $1,500,000 to $5,600,000 $4,600,000 $2,750,000 $2,600,000 $1,000,000 "Negligible" (assigned value of $100) "Negligible” (assigned value of $100) "Negligible" (assigned value of $100) 9 $9,900,000 $8,030,000 $3,900,000 $3,600,000 $1,800,000 $1,730,000 $1,726,000 $1,270,000 $745,800 > $551,000 " $234,500 $130,800 $90,000 $34,000 $30,900 $5,600 3,$2,700 to $-l,700 > $400 to $-1211500 -' "Minor" (assigned value of $100) "Minor" (assigned value of $100) $-337.50 to $-675 $-21,6OO $—371,000 $-608,000 M0000”) -221- Table A3. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Annual Per Acre User Losses from Pesticide Cancellation Pesticide Pronamide 2,4,5-T Silvex Chlorobenzilate Amitraz Endrin Use Lettuce (Salinas) Lettuce (Maria) Lettuce (Imperial) Lettuce (Other California) Alfalfa Lettuce (Arizona) Berries Ornamentals Turf Sugarbeet Seed Rice Rangeland Noncrop Prunes Sugarcane Apples Rangeland Rice Noncrop Uses Pears Citrus (California) Citrus (Florida) Citrus (Texas) Cotton Fruits and Nuts Citrus (Arizona) Other Uses Pears Apples Orchards Small Grains (Major Uses) Conifer Seeds Sugarcane Cotton Alfalfa Ornamentals watermelon Seeds Other Vegetable Seeds Tree Paint Bird Perches Small Grains (Minor Uses) Per Acre User Losses $54 to $408 $54 to $402 $50 to $55 $50 to $55 $8.05 to $38.14 '0 '0 '0 '0 '0 $14.00 $11.00 "Little" (assigned a value of $.25) $222.00 $40.00 to $-1.SO $20.00 ”Small" (assigned a value of $.25) ”Insignificant" (assigned a value of $.25) "Little" (assigned a value of $.25) ? $90.00 $47.00 $4.72 < $3.20 3 $2.88 "Insignificant" (assigned a value of $.25) '3 $170.20 $-7.89 $34.00 to $69.00 $33.00 and $1.66 to $1.94 $20.00 $9.20 $4.70 NJ'O’O'U'UOO DBCP Dimethoate -222— Strawberry Nursery Stock Pineapple Peaches/Nectarines Plums Commercial Turf Citrus Grapes Ornamentals Almonds Home Lawns vegetables/MeIons/Strawberries Soybeans Peanuts Cotton Other Berries Home Gardens Apricots, Figs, Etc. Bananas Snap Beans (Fresh) Brocolli Tomatoes (Fresh) Livestock Premises Pecans Corn Lettuce Apples Dry Beans Peppers Cabbage Grapes Snap Beans (Process) Citrus Alfalfa Tobacco Citrus Blackfly Swiss Chard Turnips Safflower Cotton Wheat Pears Sorghum Soybeans Forest Seed Orchards Tomatoes (Process) Ornamentals $21500 to $91333 $1,240 $640.24 $511 $118.92 to $302.70 $288.70 $261.08 $88.08 to $172.55 $124.42 $88.00 $38.76 $20.74 $18.18 $11.56 "Little" (assigned value of $.25) "Negligible" (assigned value of $.25) "Negligible” (assigned value of $.25) "Negligible" (assigned value of $.25) $76.70 $74.15 $43.50 $19.70 $14.34 $12.52 $7.57 to $-.02 $7.00 $6.81 $6.70 to $-4.l4 $3.87 to $—2.77 $3.83 $3.60 Z.$3.58 $.70 to $3.51 $3.48 $2.15 $1.05 to $—4.37 $1.05 to $-4.37 $1.04 $.71 "Minor" (assigned a value of $.25) "Negligible" (assigned a value of $.25) $-.55 $-l.27 $-2.25 to $-4.50 $—12.37 V) O -223- Table A4. Ranking of Uses for Each Pesticide According to Percent of Crop Treated Pesticide U§g_ Percent of Crop Treated Chlorobenzilate Florida Citrus 67% Texas Citrus 50% Arizona Citrus 5% California Citrus 1.6% Fruits and Nuts 1.0% Cotton .41% Other ”Little” (assigned value of .Ol%) Endrin Watermelon Seeds 100% Conifer Seeds 90% of direct seeded acres Other Vegetable Seeds "Like Conifer and Watermelon" (assigned value of 90%) Orchards 11.2% Small Grains (Major Uses) 9.2% Cotton < 2.0% Sugarcane < 0.2% Tree Paint "Confidential-Very Minor” (assigned value of .Ol%) Alfalfa " 0% Ornamentals " 0% Bird Perches ? Small Grains (Minor Uses) ? Pronamide Sugarbeet Seed 90.00% Lettuce 55.00% Berries 54.00% Ornamentals 5.50% Alfalfa 0.44% Turf ? Amitraz Pears 60.1% Apples 10.0% Silvex Prunes 80% Sugarcane 15% Apples 10% Rice 0.08% Rangeland 0.01% Pears ? Noncrop Uses ? 2,4,5-T Rice 12% Rangeland 0.1% Noncrop uses ? DBCP Dimethoate -224- Strawberry Nursery Stock Vegetables/Melons/Strawberries Plums Almonds Pineapple Peaches/Nectarines Grapes Peanuts Citrus Soybeans Cotton Home Gardens Other Berries Apricots, Cherries, Figs Bananas Ornamentals Commercial Turf Home Lawns Tomatoes (Fresh) Brocolli Grapes Lettuce Safflower Beans Pecans Cotton Citrus Tomatoes (Fresh) Forest Seed Orchards Sorghum Apples Alfalfa Tobacco Citrus Blackfly Corn Pears Wheat Soybeans Livestock Premises Peppers Cabbage Swiss Chard Turnips Ornamentals < 100% .l% to 95% 70% 54% 46% 44% 31% 23% 7.9% 2.1% 2.0% 0.5% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% ? ? ? AAAA 83.00% 33.00% 30.60% 20. to 25.% 22% 21% 17% 14% 12% 10% 4% 3% 2.60% 1% < 1% < 1% 0.60% < 0.50% 0.37% 0.03% °O'\J°\J°\J°\J'\J APPENDIX B CORRELATIONS BETWEEN EXPLANATORY VARIABLES AND QUALITY OF INFORMATION .APPENDIXIB Oorrelatims Between Explanatory Variables and Quality of Information 0090009 6303300 on 330 £5.00 0: use... 0:00... 13!... H0850 05 .m 56:09? 5 00.33 :0 non {0.300.393 Do:- 0:00... :0}... H0850 05 5 $2034 5 0033 30 mos N 402690 ..xL 00005:ng 5 L085: 05 an 6000:3006 3 000: 30 now 538535 no 335.6 05. 830302“ 0 no 0005 c0033 532585 «0 3.3090 0...... 5 83033 0: 003 0.0:... H 2H3): Amy), AH... mo”. Amen: Amen, oooozuoehn ax: ox: .mva, A~vun Amy), Amen: nouuaec ox: A: o\c an Assn: H: canoes o\: a. H, Amen, Assn: ANS): mamasuoooooofinu 4.. El 5... H _ E... El Boo ox: 243:, .H.11 .031: 2H2): Aden). 91m.v.~ ax: «Han: .ans Aden: .H.un «ecu: nooahm ax: «ox: H Assn: Assn, Alwyn: assessors commas: chaououos oomoooo cougars uofla o3 woos oooowooz oehowuoom \oosuoooouoom mono unmouom #0? 0.30098 8300 Ilse an 60.5000: es in? ual-0:00 so cowuesuoucu no 5330 use 30030335: 3 000: 0303000 «0 33> .0033 08330.38 .3 0.38. -225- -226- Ona. boo. 9H. 8H. So. So. So. So. 4.8. 21 So. oHH. 3on .12 RH. SH. SH. 08... 08... 08... 0.8... 08.- 08... .08... .108... :3 4.68 3850.8 ox: ox: .5! 8.!8.!8.! 8.! 3.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 3...! «82.5 ox: man. 4: 8.! 8.! 8.! o o mam. o 8 Han. 5.66 a). m. m. 8.! 8.! 8.! m. m. m. m. m. n. 3358836 4: 2.! H 8.!8.!8.! H 8.! E! 08.. 8.! 8.! some a}. H H 8.!H H H 8.! H H H H .89 388... ox: H H 8.!H H H 8.! H H H H Bfiflg H.133 ox: 8.! 8.! 8.!8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! .838 4: ox: H ETEIH H 3.! H H E! H 83828.. . Heavens-sou ex: ex: H 8.!8.!H H 8.! H H 8.! H nuisances. 8228.. :8 5.6» coo Homo... 33 3.6 5H... 83 2582 8H» 83 9382 «3038.. (3:: 600.133» .88 and ..H :83. :88 .982 :88 1.83.. . 18.6258 a coon . L348!) !-ooHuoH£cH !Hefioou! sew. 0.26095 DEED 8600 an 603000: on 3.0:. 583an 9596 so 839.585 uo 3330 are 090500355: 3 see: 030300.. no 03; c0030.. 053309900 .3 038. wNH. emu. om.” . 8H. 8H. 8H. 8H. 8H. 8.! 8H. 8H. 8.! 3588 ex: o}. 8.! 8.!8.!8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! "8;! ox: H: {a 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! H- 8.! 8.! 8.! 5.65 a). 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8...... 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 34223825 4.. 3.... H 8.... 8.! 8.! H 8.... E! a.) a... a... _ 88 a). 8.! 8.! 8.!8.!8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 8.! 0.04.... o). 8.! 8.! 8.!8.!8.! 8.! 8...! 8.! 8.1» 8.! 8.! .838. w 4.. ox: H 8.! 8.!H H 2.! H H 8.! H 858865: n {a {a H 8.! 8.! H H 8.! H H 8.! H H3805 _ 8mg ca... 5.80 ......H. goons 38 nose 83 83 0592 con. 8H» ”.592 663mm. Imus: 1000...\0>3 100:0 @090 CH 139. 10.50 nah—00nd louse unkempt 1800.63. a room !.CBoHHT!.. !!coHuoH£:H H058! x02 gm 05.8 0530 an 6005000... as 3.0.? Levee.— oce noun: :0 838585 00 5:80 6:4 883835: 3 one: 8638.. 00 8H; :83... 0.833938 .8 Home -23l- 8... 8... 8.... 8.18... 8... 8... 8... 8... 8... 8.-- 8.... 3858.3 «S. ox: 8.! 8.!8.!8.! 8.... 8... 8.... 8.... 8... 8... «85.5 a}. H- ax: 8...8.le.-- 8... 8... 8... 8... 8... H- 5.65 Q: 8... 8... 8... 8... 8... 8.l 8... 8... 8... 8... 8... ouuHHucBouoHfi {a 2... 8... 8...8.|8... 8... 8... 2... 8.! 8... 8... 82 ex: 8... 8... 8...8.|8... 8.| 8.l 8... 8.| 8.| 8... .H..m.v.~ a). 8... 8... 8... 8...8.l 8.... 8... 8... 8... 8... 8... .258 a}. a). 8... 8.l8.l8.l 8.... 8... 8.! 8... 8.| 8... 8355.... ccm 5x0» :00 0003. yawn 080 . :03 :03 9.59.2 :03 :03 £582 003%.?!“ I35: .3883... I008 mono 5 Ignaz 10.5.5 .339. .859 .9634 .8338. w 80.. .....ESoHTI .....coHuoHflcHll. £3.5ch .32 85396 2:8 5833993.... 6:3... 3880338qu 3 .328 839.585 uo 33.3 c5 3953855.: 8 no»: «3038.. we 83. 5253 33.3.88 .8 0H3 -229- 3...- 3.... 3...- 3.!- 3.... 3...- 3...- 3.... 3...- 3.-.. 3.] 8..- 3858.8 a}. a}. :T- 8..- Ho.- 8..- 8.- 8..- 8.- ANTI ST. ST- «835 a} H- «\c 8.- 8..- 8... 8..- 8... H 8..- H- H- 5.65 a}. m. m. 8... 8..- 8... 8..- 8... m. 8..- 8... m. 333.3826 a}. a). c\c a}. .m.\: c\c «\c «\c m\c n.\: o\: c\c mom—o u\: H H 3.-- H H H 2..- H H H H 363.. a}. 3..- HH.- 8.- 8.- 8..- 8... 8..- HH.- 8.! 8..- HH.-- 53% ox: ox: 8..- 8... 8..- 8... 8.! 8.| 8..- 8.| 8.l 8..- 8295.: :00 5x0... cum avg ”.03 ago :03 SH... ”.522 :03 :03 ...—.5054 833mg .32: -0u0m\o>Hu Iooco no.5 5 I33. I89: Lacuna I8.—.5 .9334 -2683: a v00... ll-ifloHol-l 53225 Hanan-...!- mem . . 9560me nEEmU 8.56 .3 gnu: an 52.5 3 00898 9888 9. ..on :0 COHHEOHCH HO i0ng 05 FuguUOflHDH-fl: 00 D8: afiduflg HO 8Hfl> C0888 gdufldflhhop .mm 0.38. . ...—W ...-.... —"'..--v' ‘v-Pi 2... AH... AH... STE-.3... 8.! a... .H... 8..- S... 3.! 38583 Q: a}. AH... 8...8.|3... 8..I 8..- 8... 8..- 3... 2...- ”83:2 Q: 8..- Q: 8...8.|3... 8..- 3... 8..- 8... 8..- 3..- 5.65 a}. AH... AH... 3.....3....3.- 3.... 3..- o o 0 AH...- 33359835 Q: 2... .H.3.ls.l_.8...§l 8... 8...:.§....§I 3... 3... 68 Q: a... 8... 3....o.l.o.... 8T 8... 8.... 8... 3... 8.... 3...... a}. 8..- 8... “QT-3.13..- 3... 3.-- Ho... 3..- 3... 8..- .833 . m .3. {a 8... 8....2l8... a... 8... 8T 8... 8.... 8... 8.5.8.. . cmm :28» com. yoga. umHo ago :03 :03 “.592 SH... :03 “.522 «gonna -39: .OuwggHu .88 no.5 ...H .33. -38 .9034 -88 .9022 b.6959. a 30.. ...-..GSaHoII- ...-83225 Hanan-...... x92 09.5098. 28 g E 08:08: an 3.3... pawn—Dinah .3 SHugucn uo 3330 can announce—Eu: o» no: 030308 uo 3H!» c0253 08339.58 .8 033. ~233- o\c o\c m\: a}. {a a}. a}. m.\: a}. o\: «\C 9.850 a: H H _ H H- H E.- o H- H- H. H. 5.68 x92 omen $25096 33¢ 095950 Oman mascuumm 33m 0,508.6 mo ems 850098 Bandung o8“. 33338.. H3238 “H595 uwuuomm 0809.85.— ou x»? 330:: ca 53189 33¢ «cons—Eon uomuoucoz 5 0068000 2:50 93.00 3 con—Hana: no 5.02. inc: :0 cons—Bowen no >373 wen nuguoouacn: 0» an»: 8332..“ uo 81$ c0253 95339.58 .3 0.309 -234- a? ome. «\c 91. H Re. 585 ox: H- H- 3... 2...- HNT. 33359836 HHT. El ST- momf E.- 3... o 8:5. ~93 3| 5.. ST. .- 3T. 2T. o no.5. noun: ”3.2523 ox: El HHT. H m.- o .836 {a «\c .2.- HNT. 3T. .3.- 3.33 ex: ex: 0 E.- El 3... 82208 HS. 3.. HHT. ST. ST. 2... all} a}. El .3.- o E.- El 9 8.5. .333 a} El H2.- H E.- El o 8:5. 3&2 ”Ban ESE-@392. 385m auHoHcomooco Rum-a. 3.3 5 u8m 8:38". 03033.. 2,3260qu 00.5 ucwuuwm x3”. . Panacea 8:8 I530 an 00.530: on 3.0:. nag-6:00 co coUEoucH no 5330 can @3088 99.6 no uncouom c093»!— ncouucnouuoo 63 038. -235- o8.- .._wmo..-....iono.-. H.- H.- H.- H.- H.- 80. H.-i H.-. 30. “v8.5.5.3 «no... . e8.- vnof H.- H.- H... H.- H... 8o. H.- H.- 80. moms». noun: 32.3 “.2 8o- wmof mg.- mva 2:.- mva ava mva ava «.3.- mva 2:.- 002.383.. 33.- vnor v8.- vHH.- vHH.- vHH.- «HH.- «Si «Si vHH.- «HH.- vHH.- o cocoa 88.. «u: goggles ”3858.3 {a H H HoT-HSIHSI HEI 8T- H 8T- 8T- H .823 a} a} El 8.1.8.18...- El El E.- El E.- El 353 ex: ax: m.- EIEI H- H- E! H- 7 El 7 838:8: ~30ng {c ox: 7 El 2T- 7 7 El 7 7 2T- 7 .HQHEHHES: amid—Bum ax: H- 7 8T- ? H- 7 8T- 7 H- H- H- 838:9? .3339 ex: 7 7 8T- 7 H- H- 8..- H- H- H- 7 “£8.35: a-m.v.~ a}. 3! H 8T- 8T- 3T- H Hovl 2.7- H 5! Helooocazug a? E! H ST- 8T- 8T- H HoT- El 7 3T- 5! o 8.5. 9&9 .58 a). HHH. ox: 8T- 87- ST- mnmf nnnf HHH. mumf nnnr HHH. 5.65 a). H H 8T- 87- HoT- H H H H H H 8.223825 .600 5x3 :00 goons. uoHo 00:6 :3... :03 0.59.2 c3... :03 gig 033.30; Liz: laumm\c>3 50:0 no.5 5 I33. no.5: nah—03¢ I939 £9034 gamma a 08... Ila-tauoHc-Il-I IIIIICOmuEflEH agave-tilt!- xufi. 8:896 0530 '36 an @8533: a 3.0:. yea-03; H.566 co 839585 no 5230 can H.338. a8... Ho £888 5938 20338.30 HS .38. -236- mme 3.1- mme anf mme mme mme 8H? ST- mme maHf 8T- u omen: ~33 ~H.H.- ~H.H.- NHL.- ~FH.- «Si «2.- .2.H.- «Bf ET- ~S.- «2..- 8.-- c macs. .398 _ 8852.3 {a mmm. {a 8T- 87- 8T- 8T- 8T- mmm. H8! 8T- 8T- 5.65 «\c ST. 8T- 8.-- 8T- H8! 87- ST- 87- ST- 87- 87! 33359825 a} 8T- 8T- 3T- 87- 8T- 87- 8T- 8T- ST- HoT- ST- H.433 {a :T- H 8T- 87- ST- H HoT- El 3T- El ST- omcs. 36.. a? El H ST- 3T- 8.3 H ST- ?T- ST- HSI ST- omcs. yuan: . . noun a}. BT- Ho.| 8T- 87- ST- 87- 8T- 8T- ST- 87- 8T- 333 {a a} .2..- §.-. ST- ST- E.- El .2.- El 5... El "825 a} «\c H- E! ET- H- 7 ET- H- H- E! H- ugflauocoz ax: {a m.- 5% E...- H- 7 El. H- H- 2.7... H... . H3885 82.2.0.5 50 5.8» 5.6 gowns 33 ago :03 :03 ”H.592 :03 c3... peso—.2 333mg ..uusz ..Oumm\0>wu 50:0 85 5 133. I38 A5034 sou—.5 Inbound $883,. a coo... l-IEBoHoII- lines-HES Hanan-Ill via madam L 9:8 258 E 88.5: 8 £qu 3.38 Ham .3tz so 83385 ac 3296 can Bug 8.5 Ho agony». 5958 9833830 .3. «Home -237- o o o o o o o o o o o o u ~95. ~93 m8- m~o.- m8? m~o.- m~o.- m~o.- m~o.- mmof m~o.- m~o.- Ref 98.- u 2.55. .68: 3853.8 m\c a}. o\c a). o\c a}. {a a}. a}. a}. a}. 0). age—gm ax: 8T- 8T- 8T- 8T- 8T- 8T- ST- .8T- 8T- HoT- 3T- 333 {c a}. 8T- 8T- 8T- 8T-. ST- HNT- 3T- HSI RT- HmT- 5835 a}. 8T- 8T- ST- 87- 8T- 8T- 8T- Hovl HSI ST- HoT- .H.-m.v.~ o\: a}. o\: a}. a}. a}. m\: a}. «\C a}. a). «\c 0 00:5. “Sing m\: o\c a}. «\c o\: n\: c\: a). o\c a}. 0).. o\: U 00:5. “Hung mono Q: c. ex: 8.! 8T- 87- H mam. m. H man. m. 5.65 H\: HHT- HHT- 8T- 8T- 3T- 2:! 8T- HHT- ST- 8T- .3! 32389825 5m 56» com Human. Has «96 8H» 8.: H.592 SH» SH» ”.522 «3338 I33: loumm\a>3 nooco no.6 5 I33. ..RHHE hue”? I950 £5034 688%,. a coon ll-Huflch-ll ---coHuoH£:H HEB-ll- xaHm 858%.. E8 ...-8.5% no 503385 H3”. 3H: Ho 3280 can 3289 no.6 Ho uncouom 5.38 333338 .3. 0H3 -238- HOV-l 8T... 3T- Hovl. ST- ST... HOV-.... ST- 87... ST- Howl. How-... 3852.3 .o\c man. a}. H3..- 87- H8..- 37- ST- mmm. How-I man. map. 5.65 Q: H H ST- HoT-ST- 8T- Hovl H 8T- HSI H 333:3 I835 {a 3T- 2T- 8T- HHVI HHT- 3T- 2T- 3T- 5|. 8T- HHT- a-m.v.~ a}. m\: a}. a}. a? o\c M\: o\c o\c a}. a). a}. mono ax: HHVI HHT- HoT-HoT-HoT- 8T- 87- HHT- 8T- 8T- :T- .833 a). {a HHVI HoT-HoT-ST- Hovl ST- 8T... 3T- Hovl ET- "835 {a {a 8.-- HoT-HoT-ST- 8T- Hovl ST- 8T- 8T- Hal 8288.. :00 :onu 50 gowns 30.3 no.6 c3... c3... ”H.582 :03 cod..— uHBQZ 8:338 139: 53303”. I005 @090 5 Lama Imus 16034 I890 Iauoont 3050.8me a 80m 13339-3- ---:oHuoH£:H--.I Ill-Hafiuo-IIII xnmm 950098.. 2.5 3 H338: no 5qu 3 0825 2.033 0» “Hov— co 539.585 no 3330 one @3089 00.5 no ”=80qu c0253 95338.30 .39 03¢. -239- 3! a... 3... 87:31.5! 8.... E... El ST: 8...: El 3852.3 ox: 8T. 8T. 8T.8.l 8.!. 8...: 8T: 8T: 8.!. ST. 8.... .H..mé.~ a}. H H “8.1.8! 8.!. 8T: 8T: H 8T: 8T: H .838 Q: Q: 3!. ASISVISVI 8T. 8T: 8T: .8! ST. E... «8&5 Q: {a 8T. 87.8.1.8... 8T. 8T- 8T. 8.! 8T. 8.... 8H; {a :T: 2.88.... ST: ST: ST: .8... 8T: 2.82:: ST: ST: 8...... mum: {a H- ex: Hal 8T: 3T. 8T. 8T. H- 8T. 8T. H.. 5.65 a). 37.. A3.... «3:187:37: A ST: “8|. HI H H. ST... 30323836 :00 5x3 cam among. “.30 noun :03 :03 H.582 :03 :03 £522 033.38 I35: IO»0&\0>3 1005 00.6 5 ..Hmom 3820 19334 18.5 Iguana? suing a coo» llbfloHeull :oHumHBcHll- ...IIIHEBXTIII Xflfim Ogmaxm gnu 5308:0033 ...—035.535 9.3“ “Huang—non no >9:qu 0:0 ©3003. no.5 uo ...—830m gun 033309.80 6.3 0.33. -240- .37. Q: 3... a} .8! .8! .8! .8! cm... .8! .8! man. 5.65 {a .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! 32355836 .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8... .8... .8! .8.... .8! .8! 3852.3, mx: .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .H..m.v.~ Q: .3! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .68 a}. .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! xgHHm Q: a}. .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! «8.52 ox: a} .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! 8238.. 50 5.8» cm... ”.8.... ”.08 88 co: 8: HES: 8H» 8H”. ”.522 8338.. -32: acuwm\w>3 .005 00.5 5 .33. .820 g sou—.5 .9334 -Scouaum a coo... . !.LG5mHo.!! --!coHuoH2cH .. !!!HnE.oa.!.! xmfi. 3:898. «5.8 228 E 0888: 8 6:3... 3 .883 38.5.. no 838585 uo .3230 can Yang no.6 uo €8qu 51.58 3033830 .an oHnua 8T .9! -241- {a .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .633 {a {a .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! «EH5. {a a}. a}. a}. a}. a}. o\: a}. a}. «\c a}. a). 82.0.5.5 o\c c\: o\: a}. a}. H..\c m.\: a}. M\: o\: m\: a}. mono a). .3! .3! .8! .3! .3! .3! .8! .8! .8! .8! .3! Tm.v.~ ox: .8! a}. .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! 5.65 {a .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! .8! cuoHHucfiouoHfi o o o o o o o o o o o o o 8:5. ~16; m3... m~0.| mmo... m~0.- m8... m3.-. £5... 93... mmof m8... m~o.l m8... o 09.5. noun... 3858.3 50 :36... com goons ago 9.50 :03 :03 .8595 :03 :3... 9582 03039.8 33:: .39.};3 .005 980 5 Law: -025 .8034 -850 g -2680.»— a moon !!§oHo.!. 83225 358...! wad. 0260me 2380 £38 an 08.63: on 3.0:. 39.6 @580 Hots. co 83.3.85 .8 3330 can 038.6 noun «0 ”.582. :83! 983368 ...B ~38. -242- m\: a}. a}. a}. a}. a}. a}. o\: n.\: a). a). 8050 A: m... ~.I mi mom. mm. o mmw. 0 ~... nnn... mmH. 5.65 mem omen 9.50096. “.03. . «6.59.00 83 @333: x92. 0.2.60me uo Oman 8:398. 033.30.. coo... 52358.. H3238 “.582 8.8% 30985 «SHE? 3 5338. 3:2 2.2”.ng ammuflcoz S 8258. 3 .anm 95.8 . g 3 08:00.: on 3.02 1:55 :0 839502..— uo auzfld can 030099 00.5 no c.5090.“ 602.500 acouuanouuou oonn Dung -243- Q: 3: .3! .3! .8! .8! ”8.2.: .3! .8! .3! m. .8! .8! 08:... 080.. .3! .3! .3! o .8! .3! 08.... .33.. 30850.3 3: 0%. 3: n3. 0 8... 8:9. 006.. ox: n3. ox: 8...- H an. 8:9. 8&0 280.0 ox: .....- m.- .8! .8! .3! 33350835 ax: .3! .8.- H .8! .3! 00:5. 026.. Q: .3! .8! H .8! .8! 8:0: 0.0.... . .000: Q: .3! .3! H H- m. 8:5. 00.6.. 3: .3! .3! H m.- o 8:3. 088 3:530 Q: .3! .3! .8! .3! .3! is; Q: Q: .8! .8! .8! .3! 83.88.. 330300032: 000300 auHoHcmmouco 0000009 003 ca 0000 0003000 0303000 . 05000000000 - 000w 0000.000 0.03. 0.000090... 0.5.00 ...-:00 >0 0090000: 00 500.5080 3 x03. 00 0038005 uo 3:36 000 003030.008 00.6 00000.. 000: 0000 000 13000 0003000 0003309000 .03 0309 -244- Q: Q: .Ql .Sl .8l .8! .Cl .NT .Nvl El .NT ....l N835 RH. 8H. 8H. N. N. N. N. N. 8H. N. N. :2. 03H: ...: RH. 20. RH. «.8. m8. 3:. mm... 08. 8:. m8. «.8. n3. «\0 a :8: . .0005. 0033 3:. So. :8. N. N. N. N. N. :2. N. N. EH. 3on 02 m8. m8. .08. 08.: 08.: 08.: 08... :No... :No... :No... 08.: 08.. Q0 0 :8: ”00000 0000: "38:02.3 Q: nmm. Q: .8l .o.l .8l 0 HHH. 8.... o HHH. NNN. 8:5. 026.. Q: 5... Q: .8l .8l .8l 0 HHH. 5... o HHH. S... 8:5. 08:: «000000 Q: m. m. .SI .SI .8l m. m. .... m. .m. m. 32.28835 Q: :7 H .8l .el .Sl H .8l El ... .N.l El 8:5. :83 Q: .HT H .Sl .8l .8l H .8l ....l ... .N.l El 8:5. 08:: . «0000 Q: 58. $0. .8l .8l .8l .Sl .8l 8N... .Sl .Sl 8N... 8:5. 026.. Q:. NR. nnn. .8l .Sl .Sl .ovl .8l 2:. .8l .8l 9H. 8:5. 08:: uxgnum Q: o 0 .8l 0 o 0 .8l 0 o o 0 80008... Q: o o .o.l o o 0 .8l o o o o 888085. £13} Q: Q: .H.l ....l El 5| 3| ....l .3l .H.l .....l .....l 82.8835. Q: Q: .Sl ....l ....l .N.l El .....l. .2..- .....l El .....l H3805 “03000000 :00 . Canon. :00 Hg 00:— 0006 :0“. 8a» 859—2 Sm... 8m“. 0592 saneuuua I000: 0000\030 .005 0000 5 I000". I002. 10000.0( 30000 0000.2 63805. a 08.. lifloHall lSHuoHEE H88ulll 0.02 00000000 05.8 300 3 0000000: 00 3.03 000003004 000000 00 030000000.“ 00 5:86 000 0030300000 0000 00000.. 000: 0004 000 H3004 0003000 0003300000 .80 0300. -245- 0m~. RN. 0mm. 8w. own. 8w. Omm. 0mm. 2:... omw. emu. 3T: moan: .833 H8. H8. H8. H8. H8. H8. H8. H8. 8T: H8. H8. ST: 8.5. .88: "3353.3 «\c a} :ul 8T: HSI Hovl .3... ST: ST: HSI 3T: 2...... any»?! Q: ~. a} 8T: Svl 8T. 8T. 87.. a. 8T: 8T: 8T: coca: 3.64 ex: ~.u a}. ST: ST. 8T: 8T. 8.!. N... 8T: 8T. 8.!. coca... .88: "5.65 a}. 3T: 3T: 8.!. 8T: HoTI 3T: 3T: 8T... .81... .8!. 3T... auoHHuconouoHpD ox: HHH.... H 8.!. .8.... 8T: H .8.... El. 5.... 3...... 3T... 095. 3:3 a}. .3!. H ST: ST. ST: H 8.!. .Htl GT. .21. QT: 8:5. .58: Evan {a 8T: Hovl 8T. 8T: HSI 8T: ST: ST: ST: ST. 8.!. 538 ex: ST: HSI ST: 8.!. 8T: ST: ST: 3T: 8T: 8T: .8.... sum.e.~ {c ox: 2T. HS..- Ht.... 5.! .3!. El 8T: HHTI 2...... ST: 8&8? .93: a}. Q: :33 .3!. 2...... 37: ET. 2...... 3T: HSI 2T: 3T: H3835 cog com 5.8... cam “.38. ”.93 $3 c3... :03 £582 :03 :03 “.595 .3338 I32: lauon\a>3 vouco menu 5 lama: lung nah—89¢ 38:5 nah—03¢ gum”. a coo... [unabsoHH—ula unicoHuungcH {laugh—Ts x»: 9.5.3me 8.56 2.50 an @833: no .Bmcuoa can 30tz o... xufi. no 838585 no 52qu can 5333056 60.6 cocoon you: 85¢ you H352 c0933 98338.30 .Hwn 038. -246- omo. omo. omo. one. omo. omo. omo. . cmo. omo. omo. omo. omo. coca: ua:oa nmn.u nmn.a nmm.u nmn.: nmm.u mmm.a mmm.u mmm.u mmm.u nmn.u nmm.: mmn.u omega pang: "ouoozuueHo u\c ox: Hmvnu Hovuu Ho... Ho... HNVun HNHIu Hm... H~vui H~vnu .mvun nouuHez ax: w. ax: Ho... Hovun Ho... o mmm. ~. o man. ~. omega umzoa {a N. {c 8T. 8.!. 8T. H mam: N. H Raf ~. 8:8 noon... ”cHuonm Q: .3... HHT. ST: 8T. 8T: 8T. 87.. .HT. .8! ST. ST. 30323826 a}. Q: a}. n\: u\: M\: Q: a). «\c a}. a}. o\c numo u\c Howl: Hovsu Hovun Ho... Hovuu Hovnn .o..u Hovun Ho... Hovnu Hovuu xo>HHm ox: .8.... 8T: 8.!.8! ST. ST. .8.... 8T: 8T: 8.!. .8l .Tmiw a}. a}. as: a}. a}. a). o\: a}. Q? a}. «\c a}. age—scan.“ =8 5.6» cam H83. 38 8.6 8H» 83 235 83 SH”. £52... 8338.. 33:: I0u0u\w>uu I005 00.5 5 ..Hnmm 18:5 lab—03¢ louse Inbound nosoouama a coon . .unnuuauuuoHouuunu coHuchch uauuunuHasuoouuunuu. x3: 25009.n— usage 9&8 S H.888: no 3.3.. 8:8 8 83.585 Ho 3230 as. SHuoHHoocoo .83 833 you: 82 ...8 H35... 59.58 3033038 .-n oHnnH. -247- «3| .8!. ST. 8T. HOT. 37.. 8T! 8T. 3T. 3.... H8... 8... 3852.3 {a .3. 5.. 87.878... 8T 8T 8.... El .2! El «835 a? 98. ex: 8T. ST. ST. 8T. 8T. Q:.. HSI N. one. was». .533 {a .3... Q: ST. HSI HSI 8T. 8T. H ST. N... R... 8.5. 8&2 ”5.68. «\c .... m. 8T. 8.... H8... 8T. 8T. m. 8.! 8T. m. ouoHHNcBBoHfi m\c H..\c a}. a}. n\c Q: a). a}. m\: o\: a). a}. name a}. ST. ST. 8T. 8T. 8T. 8T. 8T. HHT. .8... ST. HHT. macs. 3.6.. a}. HHT. HHT- Howl 8T. 3T. 8T. 8T. HHH.... 8T. HSI HHH.... no.5. 8%: «xgHHm a}. H H 8.... H H H E... H H H H eun.v.~ a). o\: 3T. HoHIHoTuHoT. ST. 8T. 8T. 8.... 8T. 8T. 829.88 5.5 5.8» cmm ummua. ”.03 none :03 :03 £595 :03 :03 H.595 033qu I33: Ioumm\0>Hu I005 Q95 :H .33. louse Iguana. Ion—.5 .9532 -8339. a coo... ......LGBoHoln... ......coHuoHBE- ...llHnanli #3: 18:00me DEB"... ......8 F 32.3! an .315 3 3898 3038 B so? co SHusuoufi Ho 3280 can. SHuuHHoocno 5.: 883 3.5 83 .5. H352 $258 9833830 .3. .36 -248- 3.- 3! 2T- 3T- GT- ST- 8T- 3T- 3! 8T- 5l 3! mafia :38 Hal 2.! 2T- El HmT- RT- .8-- .2l 2T- .8-- ET- HHT- 8:5. noun: “38:...23 Q: Q: .3! ST- ST- 8T- 8T- . ST- 8T- 8T- 8T- :T- «85?: .Q: T Q: ST- ST- ST- 8T- 8T- 7 .8| ST- ? 8:3. :93 Q: T Q: 8T- 87- ST- HSI 8T- H- .8! 8T- 7 $5.: .58: ”5.65 Q: HHT- .HT- ST- ST- 8T- 8T- 87.... m.- m... :m. HHT- 33353835 Q: 3! 2.88- Hovl ST- SVI 8T- 87- HHuotl ST- 87- ST- oocn: 5.3 Q: .HT- .Huonvl ST- ST- .8! ST- .oT... Snot- 8T- 8T- .Sl 8:5. .68: E8: Q: mam. mam. 8T- 87- 2:...- 87- ST- mnn. ST- ST- nnn. coca: .83.. Q: H H 3T- .8! 8T- 87- ST- H. 8T- 87- H omen: noun: uxgfiwm Q: 8T- 87- ST- ST- 8....- .o...- 87- 8T- 8T- 8T- 3T- .H-n.v.~ Q: Q: 8T- .oT- ST- ST- ST... 8T- 8.-- ST- .oT- BT- 82.38: cam 5.6g 50 amen. ”.03 no.6 SH... :03 956:2 :03 :3... 950:! 030308 I32: ..Ouwm\m>Hu 60:0 095 :H ..Huom Inna 10.534 louse A5034 $883: a coo... . IICBwHo-II ---:oHuoH:::H Hanan-«III x»? 95896 05.8 no 5330 0cm coHuuHHoucmo :53 0230.” you: 804 ...—0.. H352 c0153 08338500 8.56 an cannon: no .uumxuozfiom 3 ...—3.x :0 cons-boas .33 0.309 -249- How-I 3v...- «8.... Hog-I Hovl- 8T... A8..- ST- 3V...- ST- H8..- 37- BoBuEH: Q: Q: .87- .oT-ST-ST- 8.! 8T- 87- 8.! 5| 87- "83:: Q: c Q: 3T- 8T- ST- ST- ST- 87- ST- 87- o 8:2 :26: Q: nmmf Q: 8T- 8T- ST- ST- ST- .oT- Howl ST- nmnf 2.5... yoga: EH65 Q: ST- ST- ST- 87- ST- HSI ST- 8T- 8T- 8T- 8T- 33352835 Q: El ST- ST-ST-ST- ST- ST- E! 3T- 5! 3T- :8: Q: ST- ST- ST- ST-ST- ST- ST- 8T- 8T- 8T- ST- .838 Q: Hal 87- 8T- HoT-STF 8T- 8T- ST- Hovl ST- ST- is} Q: Q: 8T- .oTST-ST- 8T- 8T- 8T- .8! ST- .8! 8228: cam :18» 5o among. ”.30 no.6 :03 SH... £5054 :03 :03 H.522 «30.308 I39: -Ouwm\w>Hu 50:0 080 :H ..Hoaz I025 fig louse Luann? goo: o :8: . ll-EBoHo-II- 53225 .l-I-Hsnoall-I- mem 0.50%wa 8:8 8:8 E H.828»: 8 .nHHHam 3 .5898 2.038 3 :3: :o 83385 :0 32:3 :5 833188 .83 :88: you: 82 you H35: $2.53 9533830 .3: «Hana -250- 0:0. 0:0. 0:0. 0:0. omo. one. omo. 0:0. 0:0. omo. omo. omo. coca: nose: nmn... mmn... mmm... mmm... nmm... nmn... mmmf mmm... mmm... mmn... nmn... nmn... 00:0: H000: «030050.50 :\: :Q: .001: .ovuu onuu onun “0.1: onuu “ova: onuu .001: onun song‘s: :Q: .00.: . ax: Ao.nu onnn A001: :0... 500:: onun «ovnu .0... .00.: :fiuocu :\: “ova: .ovuu onnn onau “00:: “00:: A001: onnn onnu onun AoVan mundan:aoouo~:0 0\: :\: m\: o\: u\: 0\: n\: 0\: «\c o\: «\c a}. name :\: onuu onnu .0::: onun .oVus A031: onun .ovun “syn: .0.nu .03.: xm>nfim :Q: a H “00:: H H H .mvnu a H a H 91m.v:~ Q: a}. :\: .:\: :\: :\: Q: :\: o\: :\: o\: m.\: 03:30....— :00 :30» :00 3:39 303 00:: :03 :03 350:2 :03 :03 3:005. 0303qu 13:: 030...\0>3 100:0 mono 5 I30: .025 nah—03¢ Iago Impound . .. 0.6.800: a 000m . ...»...lfiBoEllu ......383223 32:8!!! . x02 0.3009: A 2:50 ...-56 3 00.3000: an .0380 950.5 :33 0» 0.0.:— co 833535 no 33:00 0:: 83:38:00 603 0000?— you: 85¢ :00 35:5 5033!. 9.0339300 .03 0.33. -251- 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0).. 000:8 3.: 0.: o mmn... Hmm. nmm. mmm. Nav. 2.0. 0mm. N. man. 005800304 ~.I m. 0 RN. man. 30. :3. >8. mmn. ~... mnm. 00:0: 0000: «5.65 x02 83 0000096 33¢ 00:50:00 80.: 0000.30: x02 0000005 no omen 0000096 0303000 08.. 333385 13:80: 350:2 02800 080985 8:03: B 03006:. 38: 0:033:00: 0050082 5 8:808 0: x»:: 95.00 9.50 an 0000000: 00 3.38 Hus—«:1 :0 Saul-hows 00 3.30.6 0:: 83:38:00 £03 00000.... 000: 80¢ 00.. 3052 000333 000330qu0 .hNfl 030a. -252- ST: 2T. ST: ~00. 3T: El 00.5. 0260 2T. 3!. El 02. El El .95. 0&8 385050 a} ax: 3T: 5.... El 3T: 20:5 «\c «.3. a}. as; H S... «was. .333 Q: Re. {a «S... H «av. macs. 3&2 2.00.0 ex: 7. 7 5| El El 303080836 ox: ST: El A El El .95. 026.. {c 3!. 5| H 5.... 8T: 8.5. .88: :82 Q: ST- ST- H o o .0520 {a El. 3T: 8.!. El. 3!. annim {a Q: 5.... El. 5... 5!. 83:80 xfiuficwmflaa .3830 5.808088 80309 ”.03 5 08... 8.033. 8833.. 0300000900”. 00.00 0:00.000 x02 00:00qu 0.5.00 05 an 00.5000: 00 500.5080 3 x03. :0 :03 -0535 u0 5:30 0:0 53030008 503 00003 000: H309 131:: 50500 0.8338000 .30 0309 -253- 80 a3. moo. nnH. HHH. n3. n2. HHH. nnw. HHH.. n2. mnm. Hue:— u: 80 m8. 80. 8o- 8a.- 08.- .- e8- .- 89.- .- 8a.- {was . «avocad— ugauoaaa "3333.. ex: ox..- 3| 87.8.... 8... El 5.. 2.... 5.. a... .3... ~85: ox: poo. ax... 8T. 8T. 8... H..- 3.... >8. v.- HHH.. Go. omen: 333 . {c ~. ox: . 8.! .8| 8... ~.- HHH.- ~. ~.- HHH.- H. .95. 8&2 . . EH85 ox: . H H 8T. HSI 3T. H H H H H H 33359825 ox: HHT. H 8T. 8T. 8T. H ST. E.. 98.- 5.. 3... was... ~26; {a HHT. H 8... 8T. 8T. H ST El 89. 5.. 5.. 2.25. ....E: . ‘ “82 {a o o 8... 8... ST. 8... a... HHH.- 8... ST. 3.- 5:3 a). H H §l H H H 8... H H H H 833.6 {a H H 8.... H H H 8... H H H H augatoocn: £133 Q... ax: HHT. El 2.... 5.. .HT. 2.... ST. ST. 2.... GT. augouauucs. «\c a). 8... 2.7.2.7. 3T. 2T. 2.... El El ST. 3... H3838 «easing . cum 5x3 :00 008:. avg 003 :3... :03 ...—50.2 :03 :3» 95¢! .3032...— .3:: .3955: .88 86 5 .33. -88 .989. -83 .983 . é! o .88 ..IlgoHT. ......coHuuHBEll. .lllHnBoQIII 0.589» .32 . I5 .5 v8.63: no 6933331 9580 3 33.. :0 :03 £585 Ho 3:30 a... 83.3850 :8... 883 .88 H32. H35... 5:58 3033.800 dB .38. -254- on... $6. 98. mm... a8. mm... .3... 3... ....l 8... 98. ....l «was. .25.. 30. 8... _ «8. 8o. 8... 3... 80. «8. 8.l «8. «8. 8.l «95. noon: «30050.50 {a {a El ....l 8.l 8.l El . El El .~.l El El 2.5.5 ax: a. ax: .o... .o... .o... .o... .o.-- ~. .0... .o... .0... «menu umzoa «\c N. a}. 8.l 8.l 8.l .o.l 8.l w. 8.l .o.l .o.l 8...... 8&3 ”5.65 ax: .o.-- .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... oaoHHuconouonu {a El H 8.l .o.l .o.l H 8.l El .~.l 5| 5| omen... .26.. {c .H.l H .o.l .o.l .o.l H .8.l El .~.l El El omen... .68: "none ox: .o... .o... .o... .o... .o.-- .o... .o.-- .o... .o... .o... .o... xa>HHm ox: .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... .o... 91m.v.~ m\: «\c .H... .m... ..... .m... .H... ..... .m... .H... Ah... .m... unmanuanocaz Q: ...}. El El .....l .~.l .....l El El El .....l .....l 2.39.80 “8338.. .56 5.6.. 5.. “ooh. uoHo no.6 83 83 “.582 .83 83 ....58¢ 8338.. -35: .Ouo....\o>3 .005 00.5 CH .33. -88 3.900.? 19.50 .9631 luv—60.59. . a 600.... rouge! lISHuchscu llllaflnuoolllll 302 890096 95.8 8.56 F 68.68: am .8334 can 8.0.3: on 30.2 no :03 -9585 uo .3380 can 83oHH8c8 .83 828.. you: H32. H85: :83! 30333.8 .02 3%... -255- 0:... 03.- 0:... 0.3.- 03.- 0:... 0:... 03.- 0:... 03.- 0:... 0:... 00:5. 0030.. 3.1- 02... 05.- 00H... 05... 03.- 0:... EH... 00H... 00H... 05... 0:... 00:5. 000.5 . «30050.50 a). a} .n.l 8.l .o.l .o.l .~.l .~.l .n.l .~.l .~.l .n.l se.»? a}. .... {a .o.l .o.l .o.l H Rm. 0. H nan. .... 8...... .06.. 0\: o. 0\: .3l 3.... ST. H mmn. o. H mmm. o. 00:0: 0000: ”5005 a}. El .H.l 8.l 8.l .o.l 8.l .o.l .H.l .o.l 8.l .H.l 32358036 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: mumo {a .o.l 8.... .o.l .o.l .o.l 8.l 8.l .o.l 8.l 8.l 8.l .038 a). 8.l 8.l 8.l .o.l 8.l .o.l 8.l 8.l 8.l .o.l 8.l 5.0.... 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0350.500 :00 :onu :00 0000.0 ”.03. 00:0 :03 :03 0:082 , :3... :03 £59.! 0303000 -30: 000003... .095 00.5 5 $00: .002: 1.00%? -0000 neg $500000”. 0 0000 llEBoHT ...lcoHumHEcH llHQnonull x03 0&5»ng 0.58 . §E§§3.30HE3§H¢883. 10.585 u0 00:30 0:0 53030056 .83 00000: 000: H509 H0052 c0050: 083300000 2:3 030a. -256- 3...! 3...: 3...: 8.! 8.... 8T. _ ST: ST! STI 37... 3T... 8.!. 3858.3 a}. a}. 3| 8.|8T.8.| 8.!. 8.!. .8.... 5| 8...: GT: «835. ox: one. {a .o.l 8.1.8.... 8.! 8.!. 2.... 8.1. ~. 08. 85:36.. {c 08. {a .8! 8T. .8.... 8T: 8.! 2.... 2...: ~. 08. 09.5. .88: “5.6.0 o}. H H 8...: 8.1.8.1. 8T: 8.! H 8.... 8.! H Sofia—.3826 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0}. 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 800 ox: 2T: 3.-.. 8.|8.|8T.. 8.!. 8T: 3.... 8.l 8.! .3... .836 ox: 3.... 3... 87:37:27.. 3.... El 3...: 5| El .3... sum.v.~ {a a). 8...: 8.l8.!.8.l 8T. 8.| 8T. .8.... 8.| ST. 8388.. 50 5x3 50 aces 03.. 8:0 5H”. 8H» “.58: 8H» 8H» 058.... «3033.. -32. 500...)»: .88 :80 ..H :33. :88 .385. :88 .985. . .80803 a 08.. lulEBoHollu ..llcoBmngcH Hafiwolul... 0.03 8000me £5.00 gfigfififlssgucoflgfiifiicofl ......o..& «o 3:30 05 833388 :80 889. nan: H38. H85... 50.58 9833830 .NB 3...: :TI .31.. :TI .3!. A3.... .3!. 8.! 8.-.. 3.... 8... 8.... 0.... 385800 {a Q... 2...: ..oT. 8...: 8T: 8.| 8T. 8.!. 8T: 8T: 2...... 08.02 ex: H: H..\.. 5| 8.! 8.! 8.!. 8...: H: 8.| 8.!. .7 500.0 {a 2.... 3.... 8.... 8.!8... 8...: 8.... H.. H . H 2.130228835 ox: . El .Huon.| 8.!. 8...: 8.!. 8.| 8.!. 200...! 8...: 8T: 8.!. .68 r a}. H H 8.l 8.... 8...: 8.! 8.!. H 8.!. 8...: H .620... 4. {8 .8.I 8... 8.18.1.8... 8... 8.... 8.! _ 8.... 8.! 8.... .160 ox: Q: 3.! 8.1.8...- 8.!. .8.... .o.l 8.!. 8.1 8.!. 3.... 83.8.. :00 :33 :00 00000. 003 0030 :03 :03 0:003. :03 :03 0:09.! 0303000 I000: 0000\030 1005 0000 :0 I009. 10000 50000: I008 00000: 000500002 0 0000 100330.! £832...ch lullHnBoollln 0.03 0000096 2:8 5 >0 0000000: 00 508—003-000 00 80:. :0 :03 -8085 00 .3230 0.... 83330.30 :80 «88.. 08.. H38. H35... :83! 2833-0000 .20.. .30... -258- “BI 23' 3...... 8... 8... 8... 8.... 8.!. 3.... 3...: 3...: 3...... 3858.3 3.3 H5. {a a). .8.... 8.1.8.33.-- 8.... 8.... 8...... 8.l 8.... 8.... a}. o a). 8.... 8.1.8.... 8.... 8... 8.... 8.... 8... o 5.2006. ex: o ax: 8.|8.l8.l 8.| 8.... 8.... 8.l 8.... o .80. .88... 2305. ox: 8.... 8... 8.... 8.1.8.... 8.... 8.| 8.l 8.... 8.| 8.... 33388036 a). 2.! 8... 8.1.8.... 8.... 8.... 8.... 2.... 3... 5| 3.... 88 a). 3.... 8.... 8... 3.| 8.... 8.... 8.... 8.... 8.... 8... 8.... 02.30 Q: 8.... 8.... 8.!8.!8.!. 8.... 8.... 8...... 8.... 8.... 8.!. .H..m.v.~ a}. a}. 8.... 8.l8.l8.l 8.... .8... 8.... 8.... 8.... 8.... 83.80.. :00 :30» :00 000.00. 003 0000 :03 :03 0:095 :03 :03 050.5 0033000 -000: 0000\33 I005 @000 :0 .4001 -0000 100009. 30000 g -9808”. . m 08... . .....LESSHTI. £83225 IllnHSnooIIII. x03 800E000 05.8 0.80 3 0888: no 3308 3 088.0 .838 3 .80. 8 8380.0 .30. 0H8... 8 3380 8.. 83.83880 w 080 883 .8.... H32. H35... 82.53 83ng -259- 0-.I man... 0nd:- 0.:..- 0nd... 0:.I 0H3I 0H3.- 0HH.I 0nd! and... 0.3.! 00.000 0030.. .5.- 2.H.- :0.- EH.- S.H.- 2.H.- .5.- EH- .5.- E.H.- £0.- cud-8.5.088 .38528 a). {a 8T- 8.- 8..- 8.- 8.l 8..- 8.- 8.....8T- 8T- «83.: ex: 8.! ...x: 8.!8.!8.! 8T- 8.-- ST- 8.l 8..- 8.l c305 ex: 8.! 8T- 8.- 8.! 8...- 8.- 8..- 8.- 8..- 8.- 8.3 0033:3836 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0x: 0\: 0\: 0000 a}. 8.-- .o.-.. 8.!-8.1.8...- .o..... 3.1. 8.- 8.... 3...- 8.-I .833 a). .H... 3.! 8.-.H.-.H.- 3..- ....T- 3.! ST,- GT- 2.! a-m.v.~ 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0030.800 :00 :30... :00 00000. 003 0000 :03 :03 059.2. :03 :03 050...: 0033000 I30: 0000\0>3 00:0 0000 :0 ..300 ..0000 ..00000: I0000 -00000< 0000000: 0 0000 Ill-00000005.: :030H0::H Manon-Ill 003 0000005.“. . . 9.3.00 30030000000000 .03000950003313803583 I885 00 00330 0:0 83030800 0000 00000.. 0000 ~38. «00:5. :003000 0830000000 .30 030a. 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: . 0\:. 0\: .0\: 0\: 0\: 0\: 8.28 3. ~. 0 man. men. 0. 0.8. «.0... 2b. m2... 0... w. no.5. 02.3 N. 0 man. man. «2.. n8. . :0. :N. o «... man. a?! 0&0: «500.0 x03. 83 00000me 0.0.? 00.50000 one 0002002 0.02. 00000000 00 one 0000096 0303000 . 080 . 0023380 a: 0:38 . 050.2 . 03800 080988 00:03: 3 0:302. 3.6: 0 0830308 00838: :0 008.68 3 000. . g 33830000000200.0000. 00:58:03 . 0.08.: «o 00:30 0:0 8:038:00 .800 383 08: :08. 03:5 5033 0833.008 .08 038. -261- ! m. 0N0. N. ~. ~. 0 0 $0. 0 0:. >3. 0 :00 :06... :00 0000.0. 030 0000 :30 :30 0:082 :30 :30 0:092 I000: 0000\0030 00:0 0000 3 I300: 50000 100000< .0000 .0003: luv—0,500.00 a 000..— !..!>00030!J! 500323.!!! ~33! :3: 00000000 0.0.00 00-00 >0 0000000: 00 3.3: 00:... co 830.0005 0.0 5:30 0:0 82.5. 000. 80303.. 0.00 5.508. 0.833.008 .08 .38. ! n8. . man. .8. MR... 83... o c0032. c1330.. 5088 0380.. 003 5 08.. 08308. . \90000000000 0000 0000000 03... 0.5.00 £5.00 00 0000000: 00 3.0:. 00528 8 830.085 no 00200 0.... 82:0. .00. 8.033.. 0.0.... :83... 08.03.88 ...8 .30... -262- II nun. . H n3. m3. 2:. II 0:. mmv. 000. m. H. 0 :00 3.60 :00 00009 030 0000 :30 :30 0:082 :30 :30 0:092 I000: 0000\030 I005 0000 3 I300: I0000 000002 I0000 I00000< 00000000 0 0000 . 1:00.337! Illco.0c.c..5 3.000ng 0.30. 00000000 . 0.5.00 0.0.00 an 0000000: 00 x30 08.003 L00... 8 8.02.805 00 000.00 0.... 050...... 0.0. 800.08.. a 0...... 51.08. 083-0808 .8... 00...... II 30f ~00? II 00m.I com? 80? II 000. 00m.I man. 0:. 0 50 5.60 .8.... 08...... 03.. on... 83 8.0 058... co... 8.0 0595. I000: 0000\030 I005 0000 3 I300». I0000 000002 I030 000002 0.0000000 0 0000 . L003?! lul500002§ .EBIIIIII 0.0:. 000% 0.5.00 30030000000200 50000000000000 0000000 00 0.0:. :0 030000005 00 53000 0:0 030:0: 000. 0330000 0.200 0003000 0030300000 .000 030a -263- .l o. . a I. I. In .... II a 58. 58. n3. 0 :00 5.5a :05 gowns uouo ago :03 :03 uSQZ :03 :03 ”.5651. I32: leuom\o>3 100:0 no.5 5 Lama Imus: nah—03¢ louse lagoon: b.6833. a 600m €30un Illttcogouozcn ngoculllll x31 . 3:00me 9.56 2:8 3 @838: no .333 c5 3:832 9. 3398 .888 3 33x :0 839.585 uo 5330 can 0:358 go:— 353:?" 02mm goo ucozanouuou .NE 038. I. «N... m. N..‘ N. N. N. N. . 8m. : N... .. N. N... . o 50 53» com gags ...03 no.6 :03 no: ”:38! :03 :03 ”.592 Ivan: IOuom\u>3 .605 @090 an luau". louse 19.3 18.5 Lab—03¢ lasagna: a coca lib—53o!!! [Juncofiaaflfili nus—Noel!!! gnu: ousoogfi ...-.30 2.30 3 09503: no :3:— 326 0.39.5 .90 0.38. 122 8 83.585 no 3230 as. 9.3.5.. .3: «3038.. nib 5158. 203358 -264- I So... 8a.: h. «3:339: gqu0369001\>u«3x30u0h 5 «030805 .5333. EMU 9.56 an 08:03: as $303.09 030 1309.— :0 538535 no 3330 can @5ch 33¢ 030300.— 953 c.0300 guuunouuoo .v: 0.30% .8Eocoum new 5.38:9? 058... no was. 0:0 :93 0.3.: 585 053.60.» 003.3 0 ~33qu c «02.! «:1: I. Om~. $0.: 23. n3. mnmf new... at“... N... N-.I .23. new... cow :13» can. Joana. use @030 :03 :03 ~59! :03 :03 ”.592 I32: nouom\o>3 :88 Q96 5 :33. I33 :90; :82. .9034 6.609sz a coon Inuit—330'! £83325 «IE—RT! 33¢ 830qu 95.8 . ...-.8 .5 3.38: on 31:. ~88; can 99:: _ .23 0.33. 950.5 :0 539-985 uo 330:0 can 053:3. 33: 030309. n23 ......)qu guuanouuoo -265- :TI .3!. 3T! 3T... . El ST: .3!. A3.... .21.. x253 Ba. Be. 2e. «3. H H H «8. Ba. .68 ...S. «2.. 8m. 2h. H «S. EH. H on... 3858.3 H H o H ST: ST: H .21. 3T: auméfi El. 5... H .2... 5... H: 3T. 5.... .3!. «82.5 So. So. o8. H 3.... . E... E... El o 8288... H- H.. H H.. .8.... o 5| H H.. 5.65 . m8. m8. .8.... 8m. m8. H H H El. 33H" Icoaouogu 380 380 . 08853 33 83 3:39: Rug 8338.. 2.3 8833.. H9350 H9530 «98¢ .6532 $6.32 18:32 302 no <8: 8333.. ...an 0.8.. 5? Ho <8: «0 H80 «0 #8 5 80¢ 000309 09:20 you 5 H38. 09.20 9.3.8 £530 3 08:03: on 5030200600 030308 Iona 3000 nonuso an..— 5 0093.6 :0 .23. Had. 83385 no 5330 can 8.85055ch 3 can: 0303.35- .3 33> 5253 9.0338500 -266- HHT. HHT 8T. 8T. 2T. E... H.. H: El 2T. 33% 8m. mmo. . 8m. «8. 3%. H . ope. 2%. HS. 8m. mono «mm. ~mm. H com. mum. 3H. 92. 8H. 8H. 8N. Sofiumfio 5.... .8.... H o H H mmm.: «mm... H H suméa 8T. 8T. H H 5!. 5| H.. H.. H.. H.. 833 H H H o8. H El. 8.! 8T: H 3.... 82.885 o o H.. H H.. . 5.... mmm... mm”. H.. H 5.65 H H 8T: 8y! 08. H QR. at. om~. on". 33H» ...:onouogo 8326 8396 88 383% «>38. «32 23...: «33 93m: «33 8338a :95 Ho loam Ho Ho 3.2 LB 2 Lawn L32 Loom L32 Luca 8H2, . 8H5, 8?. 5H: 53 Ho Ho Ho «o :H :H o3 8E. @3529 «x «x «x <\ «9.20 8:20 86¢ 83¢ 3:30 3:30 3o; 32» H38. 83 no.“ 233 935 an 08:30: no 503030950 03338 Scum 53% ac «30> 5 @0898 :0 833.85. Ho 5230 Be auguuousco: 3 «on: 8332: no SH; :33 9633968 6:. «Hana -267- ST. ST: H H: 8T. 336 m8... 3...: 02. RN. SN. .62 NS... 8a.- 5. 3m. 8w. Sofiuga 8T. 87.. H H H . 33% 87! ST: Anvil 3T! :41. N95?! 8T: 2:! H H. . 8m. 82.885 o H H H: H: 5.65 3T: ST: ST: H 8w. 32H» ....onouoch fleas . . 33.9: 303.: 880 .350 no 326 830.68.. «3338 H308 38:88.89. 02.0338 9.89695 :0 30095 .350 :H 09.86 BORE—H 02.088538 .550 «...-mu 5 3 62503: no .3009: 369609.638 9050 :0 838535 uo 5330 can 3330355: 3 no.5 «30309— HO «30> c0253 3.033398 4.3 038. -268- 3T... 3T: 3T1 3T... xm>uqm 8T. 03... m8. 8H. «Hm. .62 ST. HHT. «.3. 8T: 2%. 3858.3 8T: H H o H .Tm.r.~ 8.!. El .3!. H 5!. "8:5 8.!. H H Hal «8. 838.. H.. H.. H.. o H- 565 2:! H H .8] H 333.3835 8830328: 32695 uo mum—59.00 ”.2695. no 833.95.. 803.52 83: £503qu _ 3503mm.“ muonEH no 333333 £530 38 3 H.838: an .coHuoHHoocao 8332.5 no 3035 no 8332...an no 832535 uo 3330 6:0 30.33323: 0... non: 833nm.— HO and; 52.53 95338.30 .mvm 033. -269- o\: M\: x0313 8T: 3.... moon .3!. ST: 38533 «\c . a} anm.v.~ .3! H . . was? 3| ST: 82385 ST: H 565 ST. .8.... 323598016 8529.8 no Boon 8529.8 «o 8.53 8638.. 95.8 g 3 09.33: an 5.833.509. 60039.5 53 0053030 :0. :03—.3535 «0 5330 was 3033335: 3 non: 030.38.— u0 «3&— 5953 9.0330th .mvm oHnnH. . -270- ll xgzm 9H... .68 l 385an I. Sea A wound—.2 .... . 83885 H 585. com. ouoHHsanouoHfi . 8338 8338a you 938 5330 an 0883: no 58.3300 SHufiunHmma 833,...8 Ba fissuouuacm: 3 no.5 8332: Ho 81> 59.53 ucofiaHohoo 6mm 03¢ -271- Nos. . 8v. 8v. 8m. H H $5. 8m. com. a mafia .533 8m. 3m. 3‘. 8m H H H H 8m. o 8:9. 395. "82 H H 58. H El El El El El xgHHm El El H 5| 5| El H.. El El Hintw El El H El El H: El El El «83.5 Ev. Ev. v8. a2. 2.5. 9%. H8. mR. 8.4.. o 3.5. no.3 8v. 8v. v8. ma. HE. now. So. at. «3. o amen: 3%: “SmBHSHa mam... mmmr . H.. H: El El El El El 8H3: m~Hm. o. HHH. mmm. H Rm. «8. Hum. 3H. _ 5.65 So. So. Hovl nmm. 5m. . «Hp. H H El .35:N . . ICOQQHOHfi 330 330 cococcfla 2,3 2:» 3:323 games. 8332: 3.5x 833nm.“ H828 H828 83: $832 :8932 .5832 «82 no <8: 8632... “mam ”.3“. 53 Ho <8: Ho ”.80 Ho H30 5 .83 033.; 09.98 you 5 nouoc H38 8:20 938 :58 E c838: no .SHHcHHaoSo 8338.. 8.6 380 H838 fig 5 @0958 :0 838535 uo 530:0 can 033.: 90.5 mo ago.— u0u 59.53 983309900 23m 0.38. ~272- 8.30 «3. «cm. 8m. . 8n. «2.. «8. man} Rm. 3.x... 2... o .95.. . kg «3. n3. H 3.. o8. H HHH. HHH. «mo. «2.. o 8.5. . you? ”88 H H .H 58. H El HHH.- nnmr H El .853 El ST.- H- H Hal 7 H H El El is} El El H H El El 7 H- .H- 7 ~83! 8n. own. H :8. «.8. H8. 3H. 3H. HHH. we... a 85. . 3.3 Ba. Ba. H «8. SN. 25. . 8H. 8H. SH. 8.. u .95. . yuan: «33583 nnmi «Sr. 7 H- 7 El 8.! 8T nan: El 8188.. 31 28. man. HHH. Rn. 3... 2H.- Xor o2. Rn. . 5.65 H H 8T 8T «an. H. «8. «no. o8. 8w. 33? gas 8393 83.8.. H.8o 3383. 833 .23 2:8 8H3 8:3 «33 .3338 6.... Ho .8... Ho Ho «82 3.3:. #8.. LS HH Lu... L3: Loom 8:5 83. 8?. 5H: 53 Ho Ho Ho Ho 5 5 v3.89 @883. «x < ¢\ ¢\ .890 855 8.6.. 8.3 3330 52.8 33» 3o: H38. 83 you . '6 an 68:33. an 53:28.8 .3033.— louu 83969.... no 31> ..H 39.90 8 83.83.: Ho 5330 H..... 3.8:. 8.6 Ho 33.8.. 8258 3833898. .«B .33. -273- H H m8. mam. H2... o «9.5. 33H H H HHH.- 8N. m8.- o 09,5. 38: ..Homo Hal Hovl o 8.»..- Hel 33?. Hal HSI El . El . . H- 1;} H8! HoT- El Hal . HHT- "8&5 mme mom- mom. Hovl ohm. o coca: 333 81- mcmf mom. Hovl 2h. 0 8:5. .58: “38583 Hel 8T mmmr mmmf H- 8328.. o8. , mme man. man. 31 5.65 ST Hal Hal H , H ouoHHucBouoHfi BSEH . 30§H 389.: 8.08 .350 no 380 839685 8333.. 1308 03080833 35338 30960.5 :0 3009: . 9930 5 09.20 3009: 03538 350 935.8 g 3 won—Hana: no Gucci-H 339.com noHuom nap—“Ho :0 539535 uo 3330 can @333. 00.5 no “.5809 502.3 9.0333900 .nmm mung -274- . onll . mow-I . hmo. 0mm. mvm. U macaw 90304 Hovl v8.- HmH. 8... 8.... o 8:9. gang: Sumo 8T- . El 8...- Hovl H 33% Ho.- H- H- H Hm.- 91m.v.~ Hal 3| 5| H El «83.2 HSI HHT. HHm. Hovl 8m. 0 was». .833 Hovl El 8.... Hovl How. u cocoa you... «ougga HOV-I mmm.l com. Hovll mmm.l consicoum HHH.- mum. HmH. ..HN. «8. 5.65 8T H H Hal H 333.3836 . UHQHDUOUUQE nuggturo pagan-8 #052 HO .numuflxunz 385:9.- flhQnD 8w0aufl0fi 833...... 3033 .0 SHuBHBaHH. maiau 3.6 3 H.893... no .SfloHHoocao 8.838.. no 3025 .0 833.53.. 8 839585 .0. .HuHHSo 93 38.5 8.6 no .589. 5253 9333830 .Ea 3...... -275- 3T: :7: man— 95.8 a). a). .8sz a}. . .o.\c. aum€~N 5.... H «8...? HHT... ST. 33583 . 3| 8T 82.28.. 2v... HHH. £65 ST. 8.!. 333.3826 8529.8 no 9:3 85:98 Ho 8.58 8Hoflumm 9330 an @8332 no 5833.388 wag 5H3 09330-00 c3838 co 839585 no 5230 can cannons 86 no €088 5953 3833830 .3. «Hana -276- m9. u macs. .633 HHH.: o 095. 3%: Emma l _ .838 I . 38:». H . any»?! I. 3858.3 I. SHSSE «2.. 5.65 H BuHHucBouoHfi 8:302. @3338 now 9330 , 8330 3 09.530: an 58:38 838333. 030302. 93 03.239 90.5 no H..—couch coin-on 9.0338900 .03 038. -277- «2.. HS. , 8m. 9095. .26.. HH... 2... n2. 8m. H H 3... 2H. 8H. . an... H H 8... Ha... 8.... o 3...... ..an . .88.. 2H. n8. H mm... .H El H H H o 095. .16.. H H ...... H H El H H H o .85. 3...... . . 3.03am , H H H H 5!. 5!. man. 5| .3... .....m.q.~ 5.... .8!. H- 5!. 5| El 5!. El 2...... 83.8.. 5...... 2.... 8H. Hum. 8~. m3. Hen. Sn. 8... o 8.5. .26.. HHH. Hen. SH. . «a. 8.... 08. So... no... . ea... c 8.5. 92...: . .3353: ......m. 8m. nmnf A mm... H nan. o. m... on... o 8.5. .63.. 3e. 8.. ..8. Hm... H m. o. H mm... o 8.5. 8...... “5.65. . H 8T. H H w H El El 2...... 33.23835 5.... 5.... H _ El .3!. H.. 5| 5| ST. "and... 380 380. ......ch .2... 2:. 3:22,... 8.8.... 8.638.. 35$ 8.3.8.. H828 H838 38.. 5:32 .5832 .5832 3.2 .0 <8: «3033.. .8. .2... 5.: .0 <8: .0 .80 , . no .80 x S 88.. no.8... 00:20 nan 5 no.2 H38. 00:98 Slow «88... a... H.838: 3 .SHuaHHg 8333.. 8.. 38o H380 as... :H . .‘ 882.0 8 8325.... .o 52.8 H..... 383 .8: 80.. ...... H35... 89.5.... «8338.8 4.2 .38 -278- 3m. 3.... 8... 3.. 8m. HHH.. .3. v3. 2.... 3... egos... .333 a... a... 3.... 8H. «9.. HS. on... 8... 3... can. come... ...-H8: .8.... HHH. HHH. H H ...9. H fl... m3. H 3| no?! .333 H H H .8... H H man... man... H 2.... on?! no.3: . 2836 .5| .2... nan... . H. H nan. Han. nan. H H 3.3 5.. .2... 5...... H- El _ .....l H.. H. .2... ...... 81.8... m8. ...8. 2.... «8. Hon. H3. 3.... 8.... man. 8.. 08...... 8030.- SH. SH. 2.... 3H. ..-. 98... n3. «.3. 9.... 2H. c 1.5.... ...-H5... .3858... RM. 8H. 1.... Han... 8m. 8.. 3.... «8. 8o. :6. 08...... 9030.. man. man. H ..8. HHH. 8o. 02. «H... 6... 3w. 0 8.5. no.8: ......5 3| 3.... 8.! 8.! H 7...! H H 8H... 8H: 33: 155835 5| .2... H H .2! .2! H: H.. H.. H.. «8:! 828.. 838.. 88 3593.2 2.3.... .33 93.... 8.2 2:2 8.2 8.3%.... [out no Icha— UO HO .82 lulu ad la...- LOUA‘ lug lhlu u‘ Inn’— 33. 8H... 8H... . 5H: 5H: . no ... Ho ... :H ..H 303...... H.325. ¢\ .H\ <\ <\ 856 8.36 8.2 8.2 .3326 .513 3.5. 2.... H38. 80.. ...... . g g 3 nous-co: an 5030:0230 0303-0.— lOuu .3309qu no can.) H: .0935 cc :03-Incas no 5:16 .33 Sauafig .303...- louu cocoa.— 93 ...-0‘ u..- Hg ...-3!. 38339—80 .3... 038. . -279- 23.8 . H H ca. 9.5. o 0 8:9. 02.3 H H 08. mm». 3.8.... 0 09.3 3&3 £08 Hal 8T: 0mm... mi 8.!. 0 3:9. 033 8T. 8T. 28. H.. ST. 0 09.5. yoga: «xgdwm 8T. 8T... H H o almiw 8T. 87.. 5.... 3.... H: 8Heacoum mva 08. «9. mos. own. 0 095. 333 8v... 2:... van. $5. 25. 0 amend 0&8 "3858.3 H o Ev. 8v. 8.... 0 8:5. 333 8m. 8v. . So. 0 Se. 0 09.5. 0&9 “5.65 HSI HSI H8! 0 com. mmm. 33359835 ST. .8.... 5| 8...: El. «8:5 302...: 3023. Bonus 880 .850 00 380 83088.. .8HoHuu8 H308 0258000005.. 02080000 9.50395 :0 .3009: 0050 H: 00:50 g 3 60.503: no .3009: 03053038 0050 .uOu cogs-nous mo 5330 can 8.3030055 £50308 Iona common nan: 80¢ pom H352 c0253 08339.58 .93 033. -280- HSI 2b... «8.- 03. ms... 0 $5. .333 ST 2b... m8... «2.. m2. 0 $5. 9&8 £08 Howl: HHH.: coo.Hr Howl: HHH. 0 once: umxoa Hovn: HHH.: omh.n Hovun H 0 omega gang: . . “xasHHm 8T. o o H H .me.v.~ 8T. El H 8T: 5!. 83285 ST. 3| «8. Hel H8. 0 no.3. 333 H8! HHTI So. 8T. m-. 0 8:3. .38: 80858.3 o 2.0.. new. a3. EN. 0 09.5. .533 man... am. am. . HHH.. «He. 0 8:9. 3%: "5.6.5 ST. HHH.! HHH.: . 8T. HHTI SoHHucflouoHso HOT! 29!. «.3!... H 37.: . saunas—4 883033.25. 30:69.5 uo 8859.00 uuavoumfi mo 833.qu 803:0: macaw 030308 8638a Boa: no SHHBHBoHa . 2330 g 5 08:33 no .coHuoHHoocou 8638.. Ho Boon-H Ho SHuBHbaHn :0 83.385 00 5330 new 83339.8 «3238 83 833 you: 83 .5. Hung 5253 3.33830 .9! «Hana -281- 23.... :7... moan 0\: 0\: 003.3 a). {a eumim El 8.!. 83280 El 8T. . 3358.3 H8... man... 0 00:5. 0033 2h. 50. 0 039. 0&3 "5005 2T 3T . 3523825 23!. a 0003.5 85.2030 00 330 85:93 0o 8003 8333.. 3 0.3.00 an 009.0000: 00 300303000: 00000000 5m: 000039.00 :0 0030-08—5 00 5330 0:0 0030300000 030.3000 800 00000.. 000: 80¢ 00m H0052 000300 0003300000 .30 0309 -282- men. ~00. com... H 00000000 000 000.00 mumo x0300 elm . v . N 0300800 000050000 0 00000 00300 0 omens 0000: «00005 0003000000030 00000.2 «00000000 03.00 >0 0000000: 00 ~000000000 0030000000: 0000 $0000 000 0030300000 0303000 8000 00000.0 0000 0000 000 H0005 0003000 00000300000 .N00 0.300. -283- ~00. 02.. ~00... 0.0.0. 000. : 0000.. 000.10.300.00 HP! HP! 02.. 000... ...,000... 000. . 000. 000. 80.. 0 09.00.0008 £000 0 0 80. 000. . 0 El 0 0 0 000000 El El 0.. El El . El 0 El El 01.0.00 El 5.... 80. El El E... El El El 0000080... 02.. 00.0. 000. 000. 000. 00.0. «B. 000. 000. 0 00:00. .0033 00.. 80. 00.0. 000. 000. 00.0. 08. 000. 00.. 0 00:00. 0000: . «000050500 «00. SN. 0 000. 0 0.00. 80. 0 000. 0 00:00 0030.0 0.00.. 000. 0. 000. 0 80. 02.. 0 000. 0 00:00 0000: "0000...... 0 0 El 80. 0 El El El El 00000000000005 El El 0 El El 0.. El El El 0000000 0008 00000 00:00:30 0:00 0>00 00:32.00 0000000. 000000000 005\ 000000000 000080 08008 00000 -2000: -0500: -2000: 00.000 00 <00: 000000000 0000 0000 50: 00 <00: 00 008 00 008 :0 00:05 0000000. 000000 0000 00004 0000.0. 000 0.0.00 300 an 0000000: 00 0030300000 00003000 0000 00000 0000000 0000 00 0000000 00 003005005 00 00000000 0:0 80000000000 000000000 .800 00003 000: 00090 00:05 0003000 00000000008 .000 0000.0. -284- 000. 000. 80. ~00. 00.0. 000. $0. 30. 00.0. 0%. 0 00000 .0033 man. 000. 000. 000. 000. 000. 000. 000. 000. 0~0. 0.00000 .0000: 0000 000. 000. 0 com. 000. 0 on~.u om~.- 0 000.. 000000 000.: 000-- 0 0- 000.: 0 0- 0- .00.: 000.: 010.0.~ Svl .El .2l 8N. Atl ASI Svl El “Bl Evl 000000000 ~00. ~00. 02.. 00.0. 03. ~00. ~00. ~00. 0m~. mom. 0 00:00 kg”— 00~. 00~. 000. 000. 000. 0~o. 0~0. 0~0. 000. 00~. 0.00000 .0005: «0000000050 000. 000. 0~0. 0 000. 000. 000. ~00. oo~. 000. 0.00000 - . .0038 000. 000. 000. 0 0m~. 000. 00~. 0~m. 000. 000. 0.00000 .0008 000.005 .00.. 000.: 00... .00.: com. 00... 0 0 o 0 000000 100000005 :ul :ul 0 0 AEl AEI 0.. 0: 0: 0: 00.0005 0000000 0000000 0000 000000000 0>0000 0000000 0>0000 00000 00000: 00000 000000000 .000 uo 5.00 no 00 00.000 1000? 00.000 0.00004 $000 1000.? 10000 0:000. 0305 000.00 0003 0003 - 0003 0003 0003 :0 00 0000000 0\ 0x . 0x. 0x 00:06 00:06 00.000 000008 000008 00000 00000 0008. 0.004 .0000 0.0000 0350 an 00.03000: 00 .00300000000 000000000 08.00 000000690... uo 0:0; 5 0000000 00 000.003.0805 00 000003 0:0 80000000000 000000000 .800 00008 0000 0000.0. 0005.0 00300 2000000008 .30 0000.0. -285- mNHf mme 8m. H o o 8:3. 3.3 So... So... «8. H o o cocoa yang: “mono ‘ 8T: 8T: 96. 8w... ST: .838 ST. 87.. .8.... 3!. H anmaé Hal 2:! ST. ST: 8N. maggot Sn... 8%: ma. 2%.. 8v 6 3:3. .333 2...: ~21: awn. SN... o9. o omen... 93a: “385an 08. oov. H 8v. CON. 0 00:5. .3304 08. 8... H 8N. 8v. 0 8:5. .69.: . "5.65 2:! ST: HSI H ems. 333:3825 8T: 8T. El 8T. 5.... «82.2 3035 BoogH 303.: 88c 355 no 380 832685 03033.. H308 3880850: 0298008 8qu :0 3009: .350 5 0936 5 >n 03:30: no 503330.30 03338 no Bonn-H UHBQBoulonoom .350 :0 53385 Ho 3330 Han 833188 8638.. .88 833 you: H38. Hung 5853 9833858 .mmm oHan. -286- 8.! o . ...HH. 8w. 0.8. u can»... .3 .8I o 9H. v9. 8... u was... 9&8 88.. .8!. .HT. 8...: 8.... H .833 8.!. H H H: .8.... aum.v.~. 8.!. 2.! 8m... 8...: .2... 8398.... 8.! .3... SN. .8.... «mm. a ones. ...3 ‘ .8l 2.... RN. 8...: ....m. o 8:9. 3...... . «3358.3 o ~Hq. «H... H..... «H... u 095. .833 o 9...... 3m. 3... 8m. 9 8...... noon... . EUR... .8.... El 2.... .o.l 3.! 333.3836 8.!. .3!. 2...... H .8... «.53 3330325.: 3030.... no 9.8.5300 ”.260: uo 338.98.. 309.32 anon: 0303»?— 8Honu£ 3895 .0 833.33.. g 3.8 .5 .333: on ...oHaoHHoocfi 8338.. :8. 38...: no 83:353.. 8 83385 no 3230 93 832328 8.033.. :8... 883 you: H38. H35... .3258. «83338 .8: £3... -287- 5.... 3| mono m}. a}. .835 a? fi\c. Humi~ ST. ST. 82.283 5.... 8T. 3858.3 m8: H 0 3.5. .333 3%. H 0 095. 0&3 _ "5.65. 3!. 8T. SaHHucfiouoHfi 28.... H No.53 85:38 no 330 8529.8 no 0868 «3303.. 9:8 g >0 09.503: 00 530303008. 000000.!— 5.3 00.33030 :0 cons-nous no 5330 can 830300.30 030303 loam 0003a 000: H38. 1352 50303 0303300000 4.8 033. -288- o ammo II x9>dfim II s1m.v.m I 82958 . I _ 3338.3 So. 565 H 333.3825 H «Bug 5:303 «Begum.— .uoH £35 3 an 6.09.63: on 55.333 538.333. 03033.. :0 Squguca no 5:30 93 83389.8 863:: loan «83.. non: ~38 ~35: 8258. 2033898 £8 cine -289- _ five: 38o. 33:8 anon 5 09.20 ~38 . com... Bnoo 35:00 am?» 5 09.65 9.84 nan 8a... 353 86398 3 3% n82 m8... 233532 5:3 Banana 88¢ mmvr 833mg 5? Bug 834 2%... 933334 no <8: _ Sc... 03338 no axon: o ..zégqumfioflc no 38 o . fiéogofiaom no ”.80 2.5a Slaw an 68:53: no .330 35:00 anon 5" ago :0 saga-nous no 3:30 05 mad—cum gav— agofinom ESE :09...qu 303309.30 .mom 0.38.. -290- 8%: 83808... no 83> 5 09.20 ~38. 8m... 83808.. Ho 83, E 335 82 08 8.6.... 080 no 8?— 8~.... 02:8 «30380 m: 093:8... 8.02 . m8... £38032 5:: 03809 «82 Se... 86380 5:: 0325. 3.3 $1 832032 uo {3330 >2. «3338 no {3230 x 8m... 23203? no <32; 02... . «3338 No <33» 9.30 3 3 00.5000: an 5030.603 no «30> 5 000096 :0 0039535 no 33000 0:0 @0353. #02 030308 02mm 0003qu 000330.300 .05 038. -291- 00. 303.: 0380 3.0. 3009: 00300000000: Ommf. 302.2: 3.30.5000 90... 00000 0050 no 000308.... 00 3009: o ‘ 330 5330000 h5.50. 5.00.0030 00:00 03:00 an 00.5000: 00 .3009: 03900000300. _ 0050 00 0030-085 uo 33000 000 003000 0.03 0303000 0.30 0003000 0003300000 .HB 030a. -292- .Hmo.l HHH. oom.l OhgfluUflUna—hfl: 9H. HUG-8.3m HO pug-50:8 OH. 08080 00 833.3: on. 09000002 on. “98: OH. EMU nuouaEH uo couuanquuawo 0.50 3 00380: no .303: no 5330503 no 332085 00 3:30 05 9.3.5. 0.0:. 030330 0:30 5058. 30338000 .20 03.0. -293- 80.... «RN . 0000a H9300 no 3000 0000a H9300 no 000000 . g 05.00 an 00.5000: 00 500030 ...80 co 830.085 00. 5:30 05 83:2 in. 80038.. 02.0 5308 0833330 .20 038. BIBL IOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Anderson, Elizabeth L. 'Carcinogen Risk Assessment in the Environmental Protection Agency." Association of Food and Drug Officials Quarterly Bulletin 44, No. 1 (January 1980): pp. 65-66. Anderson, Lee G. and Settle, Russell P. Benefit-Cost Analy- sis: A Practical Guide. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1977. Andrews, Richard N.L. "Values Analysis in Environmental Policy.“ Policy Studies Journal 9, No. 3 (Winter 1980): pp. 369-378. Aspelin, Arnold L., and Ballard, Gary L. ”Economic Aspects of Current Pesticide Regulatory Programs and Outlook for the Future." Paper presented at the American Meeting of the Agricultural Economics Association, August 1981. Baldwin, John R. The Regulatory Agency_and the Public Corpo- ration. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co., 1975. Bartlett, Randall. Economic Foundations of Political Power. New York: The Free Press, 1973. Brickman, Ronald and Jasonoff, Sheila. ”Concepts of Risk and Safety in Toxic Substances Regulation: A Comparison of France and the U.S.” Policy Studies Journal 9, No. 3 (Winter 1980): pp. 394-403. "Cancer Risk: An Interview with Dr. Eflizabeth Anderson.” EPA Journal 5, No. 3 (March 1979): pp. 8-9 and 40. Cohen, Dave. "Guarding Against Cancer.” EPA Journal 4, No. 3 (March 1978): pp. 12-13. "Congress Expedites Pesticide Program." EPA Journal 4, No. 8 (September 1978): p. 34. Council for Agricultural Science and Technology. Impacts of Government Regulation on the Development of Chemical Pesticides for Agriculture and Forestry. Ames, IA?— Council for Agricultural Science and Technology, January 1981. ~294- -295- . Social and Economic Impacts of Restricting Pesti- cide Use in Agriculture. Ames, IA: Council for Agri- cultural Science and Technology, December 1980. Davis, Otto A. and Kamien, Morton I. "Externalities, Infor- mation and Alternative Collective lAction," In Public Expenditure and Policy Analysis, pp. 82-104. Edited By Robert H. Haveman and Julius Margolis. Chicago: Rand McNally College Publishing Co., 1977. Downing, Paul B., and Brady, Gordon L. ”Constrained Self- Interest and the Formation of Public Policy.” Public Choice 34 (1979): pp. 15-28. Downs, Anthony. "A Theory of Bureaucracy." American Eco- nomic Review 55 (May 1965): pp. 439-446. Dreyfus, Daniel A. ”The Limitations of Policy Research in Congressional Decision-Making.” Policy Studies Journal 4, No. 3 (Spring 1976): pp. 269-273. Ebner, Lawrence S. "A Concise Guide to RPAR, Cancellation and Suspension Proceedings Under FIFRA." Washington, October 1981. . 'EDF v Costle: EPA's New Case for Pesticide Reg- ulation.” Env1ronmenta1 Regulation Analyst 2, No. 1 (December 1980): pp. 6-8. . ”Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration: How EPA Has Improved Pesticide Review.” Environmental Reg- ulation Analyst 1, No. 4 (March 1980): pp. 2-5. Eckert, Ross D. ”On the Incentives of Regulators: The Case of Taxicabs.” Public Choice 14 (Spring 1973): pp. 83-99. Edelman, Murray. Political Langgage: Words That Succeed and Policies That Fail. New York: Academic Press, Inc., 1977. Edmunds, Stahrl W. ”Environmental Policy: Bounded Ration- ality Applied to Unbounded Ecological Problems.” Policy Studies Journal 9, No. 3 (Winter 1980): pp. 359-368. Environmental Studies Board Committee on Prototype Explicit Analyses for Pesticides. Regulating Pesticides. Wash- ington: National Research Council, 1980. "EPA's Todhunter Tells NACA What Reforms the Agency Will Deliver and When." Pesticide and Toxic Chemical News, 28 April 1982, pp. 12-15. -296- Epp, Donald J.: Tellefsen, F.R.: Shute, G.A.; Bear, R.M. and Wilkinson, K.P. Identification and Specification of Inputs for Benefit-Cost Modeling of Pesticide Use. Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, August 1977. "Federal Insecticide Fungicide and Rodenticide Act." 7 U.S. Code Annotated, Section 136. Feller, Irwin and Flanary, Patricia E. "Economic and Politi- cal Aspects of the Benefits and Costs of Food Regula— tion.” Association of Food and Drug Officials Quarterly Bulletin 44, No. 1 (January 1980): pp. 47-59. "FIFRA Changes, OPP Reorganization Prime Topics of Pesticide Regulation Course.” Pesticide and Tbxic Chemical News, Fiorino, Daniel J. and Metlay, Daniel S. ”Theories of Agency Failure, or, Why Regulatory Agencies Continue to Be Unreliable When the Solutions Seem So Obvious.” Paper presented at Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, 1977. Fraenkel, R. and Hadwiger, D. 'The Agricultural Policy Process.” Policy Studies Journal 4, No. 1 (Autumn Freeman, A. Myrick, III. The Benefits of Environmental Improvement: Theory and Practice. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979. Freeman, Linton C. Elementary Applied Statistics: For Students in Behavioral Sciences. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1965 Gangstad, Edward O. “Benefit/Cost Analysis of Silvex Can- cellation.” Journal of Aquatic Plant Management 20 (1982): pp. 45-49. Green, M.B. Pesticides: Boon or Bain? Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1976. Gusman, Sam; von Moltke, K.; Irwin, F. and Whitehead, C. Public Policy for Chemicals: National and International Issues. Washington: The ConservatiOn Foundation, 1980. Hapgood, Fred. ”Risk Benefit Analysis: Putting a Price on Life.” The Atlantic Monthly, January 1979, pp. 33-38. -297- Haveman, Robert H. and Weisbrod, Burton A. "Defining Bene- fits of Public Programs: Some Guidance for Policy Analysts." In Public Expenditure and Policy Analysis, pp. 135-160. Edited by Robert H. Haveman and Julius Margolis. Chicago, IL: Rand McNally College Publishing Co. 1977. Hildreth, R. James. "Economists, Regulation and Public Policy.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61, Number 4, Part 2 (November 1979): pp. 755-759} Hirschman, Albert 0. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970. Honeycutt, R.C., and Ballantine, L.G. ”Application of Mathe- matical Modeling Results for Environmental Risk Assess- ments.“ Paper presented an: American Chemical Society Symposium, September 15, 1982. Johnson, Edwin L. ”Risk Assessment in an Administrative Agency.” The American Statistician 36, No. 3, Part 2 (August 1982): pp. 232-239. Joskow, Paul L. "Inflation and Environmental Concern: Structural Change in the Process of Public Utility Price Regulation.“ Journal of Law and Economics 17, No. 2 (October 1974): pp. 291-327. Kelman, Steven. ”Regulation by the Numbers: A Report on the Consumer Product Safety Commission.“ The Public Inter- est 36 (Summer 1974): pp. 83-102. Kohlmeier, Louis M. “The Regulators and the Regulated." In The Political Economy of Federal Policl, pp. 256-260. Edited by Robert H. Haveman and Robert D. Hamrin. New York: Harper and Row Publishers, 1973. Lave, Lester B. The Strategy of Social Regulation. Washing- ton: The Brookings Institution, 1981. Lowrance, William W. Of Acceptable Risk: Science and the Determination of Safety. Los Altos, CA: William Kauf- mann, Inc., 1976. Majone, Giandomenico. ”Process and Outcome in Regulatory Decision-Making.” American Behavioral Scientist 22, No. 5 (May/June 1979): pp. 561-583. March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A. Organizations. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1958. Maynard-Moody, Steven and McClintock, Charles C. ”Square Pegs in Round Holes: Program Evaluation and Organi- zational Uncertainty.” Policy Studies Journal 9, No. 5 (Spring 1981): pp. 644-666. -298- McCraw, Thomas K. ”Regulation in America: A Review Article." Business History Review 49, No. 2 (Summer 1975): pp. 159-183. McFadden, Daniel. ”The Revealed Preferences of a Government Bureaucracy: Empirical Evidence.” Bell Journal of Economics 7, No. 1 (Spring 1976): pp. 55-72. McKenzie, Richard B. and Macaulay, Hugh H. ”A Bureaucratic Theory of Regulation.“ Public Choice 35 (1980): pp. 297-313. Mishan, E.J. Cost-Benefit Analysis: New and Expanded Edi- tion. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1976. Mitnick, Barry M. The Political Economy of Regulation: Creating, Designing and RemovingRegulatory Forms. New York: Columbia University Press, 1980. Moffitt, L. Joe and Farnsworth, R.L. 'Bioeconomic Analysis of Pesticide Use.” Agricultural Economics Research 33, No. 4 (October 1980): pp. 12-18. Mueller, Dennis C. Public Choice. New York: Cambridge Uni- versity Press, 1979. National Research Council. Pesticide Decisiog;Making, Wash- ington: National Academy of Sciences, 1977. National Research Council. Decision-MakinLin the Environ- mental Protection Agency, vols. 11a and 11b. Washington: National Academy of Sciences, 1977. Nelkin, Dorothy and Pollak, Michael. ”Problems and Proce- dures in the Regulation of Technological Risk.“ In Making Bureaucracies Work, pp. 259-278. Edited by Carol Ii. Weiss and Allen H. Barton. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications, 1979. Niskanen, William A. 'Bureaucrats and Politicians.” Journal of Law and Economics 18 (December 1975): pp. 617-643. . "Competition Among Government Bureaus." American Behavioral Scientist 22, No. 5 (May/June 19795: pp. Noll, Roger G. ReformingRegulation. Washington: The Brook- ings Institution, 1971. . 'The Behavior of Regulatory Agencies.” Review of Social Economy 29 (March 1971): pp. 15-19. -299- Owen, Bruce M. and Braeutigam, Ronald. The Regulation Game: Strategic Use of the Administrative Process. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co., 1978. Park, Rolla Edward, ed. The Role of Analysis in Regulatory Decisionmaking: The Case of Cable Television. Lexing- ton, MA: Lexington Books, 1973. Peltzman, Sam. ”Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19, No. 3 (October 1976): pp. 211-248. Porter, Michael E. and Sagansky, Jeffrey F. ”Information, Politics and Economic Analysis: The Regulatory Decision Process in Air Freight Cases." Public Policy 24, No. 2 (Spring 1976): pp. 263-307. Portney, Paul R., ed. Current Issues in U.S. Environmental Policy. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978. Posner, Richard A. “Taxation by Regulation.“ Bell Journalof Economics and Managgment Science 2, No. 1 (Spring 1971): pp. 22"50. . “Theories of Economic Regulation.‘ Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5, No. 2 (Autumn, 1974): pp. 335-358. Reynolds, Larry. "Foundations of an Institutional Theory of Regulation.“ Journal of Economic Issues 15, No. 3 (September 1981): pp. 641-656. ”Risks and Challenges: An Interview with Dr. John A. Tod- hunter.“ EPA Journal 7, No. 10 (November/December 1981): pp. 10-12. Roberts, Marc J. “An Evolutionary and Institutional View of the Behavior of Public and Private Companies.” American Economic Review 65 (May 1975): pp. 415-427. Rodricks, Joseph V. I'Risk/Benefit Assessment: Or Some Notes on Cost-Benefit Analysis in Regulation of Food Chemi- cals.” Association of Food and Drug_Officials Quarterly Bulletin 43, No. 1 (January 1979): pp. 3-12. ii Roos, Leslie L., Jr. and Liroff, Richard A. “Political Dynamics and Environmental Policy.” Policy Studies Journal 1, No. 4 (Summer 1973): pp. 226-233. “ ”RPAR Process Reformed Almost Beyond Recognition.“ Pesticide and Toxic Chemical News, 28 April 1982, pp. 9-11. ’fifi -300- Russell, Milton and Shelton, Robert B. 'A Model of Regula- tory Agency Behavior.“ Public Choice 20 (Winter 1974): pp. 47-62. Sabatier, Paul. 'The Acquisition and Utilization of Techni- cal Information by Administrative Agencies.‘ Adminis- trative Science Quarterlyy 23 (September 19785: pp. 396-417. Samuels, Warren J. “Legal-Economic Policy.“ Policy Studies Journal 2, No. 1 (Autumn, 1973): pp. 12-15. . ”Public Utilities and the Theory of Power." In Perspectives in Public Regulation: Essays on Political Economy, pp. 1-337 Edited by Milton Russell. Carbon- dale, IL: Southern Illinois University Press, 1973. , Schmid, A. Allan and Shaffer, James D., ”Regula- tion and Regulatory Reform: Some Fundamental Concep- tions." In Law and Economics: An Institutional Per- spective, pp. 248-266. Edited by Warren J. Samuels and A. Allan Schmid. Boston, MA: Martinus Nijhoff Publish- ing, 1981. and Shaffer, James D. ”Deregulation: The Principal Inconclusive Arguments.” East Lansing, MI, 1982. Schmid, A. Allan.'Analytica1 Institutional Economics: Chal- lenging Problems in the Economics of Resources for a New Environment.” American Journal of Agricultural Eco- nomics 54, No. 5 (December 1972): pp. 893-901. . I'Political Economy of Public Investment.” East Lansing, MI, January 1980. . Property, Power and Public Choice: An Inquiry into Law and Economics. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1978. Schuck, Peter H. "Regulation: Asking the Right Questions." National Journal, 28 April 1979, pp. 711-717. Schwerin, Don S. and Coyer, Brian W. ”Institutions and Knowledge as Determinants of Regulatory Performance: Toxic Chemicals and Electricity." Paper presented at the Symposium on Regulatory Policy, Houston, TX, Novem- ber 1979. Shaffer, James D. "Observations on the Political-Economics of Regulations.” American Journal of Agricultural Eco- nomics 61, No. 4, Part 2 (November 1979?: pp. 721-731.i‘— -301- Shapiro, David L. and Shelton, Robert B. I‘The Application of an Agency Decision-Making Model." Public Choice 32 (Winter 1977): pp. 51-65. Starling, Grover. The Politics and Economics of Public Policy: An Introductory Analysis with Cases. Homewood, IL: The Dorsey Press,‘1979. Steiner, Peter O. "The Public Sector and the Public Inter- est.” In Public Expenditure and Policy Analysis, pp. 27-66. Edited by Robert H. Haveman and Julius Margolis. Chicago, IL: Rand McNally College Publishing Company, 1977. Stigler, George J. 'The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2, No. 1 (Spring 1971): pp. 3-21. Thurber, James A. 'Legislative-Administrative Relations.” Policy Studies Journal 5, No. 1 (Autumn 1976): pp. 56-65. U.S. Congress Office of Technology Assessment. Environ- mental Contaminants in Food. Washington: U.S. Govern- ment Printing Office, December 1979. U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on 2,4,5-T. The Bio- logic and Economic Assessment of 2,4,54T. Washington: U.S. Department of Agriculture, February 1979. U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on Amitraz. The Bio- logic and Economic Assessment of Amitraz. washington: U.S. Department of Agriculture, August 1978. U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on DBCP. The Biologic and Economic Assessment of DBCP. Washington: U.S. Department of Agriculture, November 1977 and July 1978. U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on Dimethoate. The Biolggic and Economic Assessment of Dimethoate. Wash- _ihgton: U.S. Department of Agriculture, June 1979. U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on Endrin. The Bio- logic and Economic Assessment of Endrin. Washington? U.S. Department of Agriculture, November 1976 and Feb- ruary 1977. -302- U.S. Department of Agriculture/U.S. Environmental Protection Agency/State RPAR Assessment Team on Styrchnine, Styrchnine Sulfate, 1080/1081. The Biologic and Boo- nomic Assessment of Strychnine, Strychnine Sulfate, 108071081. Washington: U.S. Department of Agriculture, March 1977. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. ”Draft Rules Governing Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration (RPAR) Pro- ceedings: Criteria for the Initiation of RPAR Proceed- ings.” Washington, 1982. . I'Health Risk and Economic Impact Assessments of Suspected Carcinogens: Interim Procedures and Guide- lines.“ Federal Register 41, No. 102 (May 25, 1976): pp. 21402321405. . I'Mutagenicity Risk Assessments: Proposed Guide- lines.” Federal Register 45, No. 221 (November 13, 1980): pp. 74984-74988. . ”Pesticide Registration Guidelines (40 CFR Part 163, Subparts A-P; New).' Federal Register 47, No. 8 (January 13, 1982): pp. 1826-1829. . “Regulations for the Enforcement of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide and Rodenticide Act.” Code of Federal Regulations 40, Chapter 1, Parts 162-164, July 1983. U.S. Environmental Protection ,Agency’ Office of Pesticide Programs. ”2,4,5-T: Position Document 2/3.” Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 15 March 1979. . "Amitraz (BAAM): Position Document 1.” Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 4 March 1977. . "Amitraz (BAAM): Position Document 3.” Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection. Agencyy 6 January 1979. . "Amitraz (BAAM): Position Document 4.“ Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 4 June 1979. . "Chlorobenzilate: Position Document 3.“ Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 11 July 1978. . ”Chlorobenzilate: Position Document 4.“ Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 13 February 1979. -303- . “Compound 1080 and 1081: Position Document 1." Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 27 October 1976. . “Decision and Emergency Order Suspending Registra- tions for Certain Uses of 2-(2,4,5-Trichlorophenoxy) Propionic Acid (Silvex); Notice of Intent to Cancel Certain Registrations of Pesticide Products Centaining Silvex; Suspension Order for Silvex.“ Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 28 February 1979. . 'Dibromochloropropane (DBCP): Final Position Document.” washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 6 September 1978. . 'Dibromochloropropane: Suspension Order and Notice of Intent to Cancel.” Federal Re ister 44, No. 219 (November 9, 1979): pp. 65135-65179. . ”Dimethoate Position Document 2/3.‘ Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 19 November, 1979. . “Endrin: Notice of Intent to Cancel Registrations and Denial of Applications for Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Endrin, and Statement of Reasons.” Federal Register 44, No. 144 (July 25, 1979): pp. 43632- 43657. . 1"Endrin: Position, Document 2/3.' Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 18 October 1978. . ”Final Determination Concerning the Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration for Certain Uses of 2,4,5-T; Notice of Intent to Hold a Hearing to Determine Whether or Not Certain Uses of 2,4,5-T Should Be Can- celed; Publication of Final Position Document Concerning A11 Non-Suspended Uses of 2,4,5-T.‘ Federal Register 44, No. 241 (December 13, 1979): pp. 72316-72341. . I'Fluoroacetamide (Compound 1081): Position Docu- ment 2.” Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 28 February 1980. . "Notice of Determination Not to Initiate a Rebut- table Presumption Against Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Carbaryl.‘ Federal Register 45, No. 241 (December 12, 1980): pp. 81869-81876. . “Notice of Determination Not to Initiate a Rebut- table Presumption Against Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Triallate.” Federal Register 45, No. 242 (December 15, 1980): pp. 82 49-82352. -304- . “Notice of Intent to Cancel Registrations and Deny Applications for Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Pronamide." Federal Register 44, No. 209 (October 26, 1979): pp. 61640-61651. . "Notice of Presumption Against Registration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Chlorobenzilate.” Federal Register 41, No. 103 (May 26, 1976): pp. 21517-21519. . "Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing 2,4,5-T.' Federal Register 43, No. 78 (April 21, 1978): pp. 17116-17157. . "Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Amitraz.” Federal Register 42, No. 66 (April 4, 1977): pp. 18298-18303. . "Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Dibromochloropropane (DBCP)." Federal Re - ister 42, No. 184 (September 22, 1977): pp. 48026-48045. . ”Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Dimethoate." Federal Register 42, No. 176 (September 12, 1977): pp. 45806-45816. . ”Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Endrin.” Federal Register 41, No. 145 (July 27, 1976): pp. 31316-31337. . ”Notice of Rebuttable Presumption Against Regis- tration and Continued Registration of Pesticide Products Containing Pronamide.” Federal Register 42, No. 98 (May 20, 1977) pp. 25906-25911. . "Notice of Termination of Rebuttable Presumption Against Registration, of ZPesticide iProducts Containing Fluoroacetamide (Compound 1081).” Federal Register 45, No. 41 (February 28, 1980): pp. 13189-13191. . "Pesticide Products Containing Dibromochloropro- pane (DBCP) and Statement of Reasons: Intent to Cancel the Registrations or Change the Classifications." Federal Register 42, No. 212 (November 3, 1977): pp. 57545-57548. -305- . “Pesticide Products Containing Dimethoate: Final Notice of Determination Concluding Rebuttable Presump- tion Against Registration and Continued Registration.” Federal Register 46, No. 12 (January 19, 1981): pp. 5334-5369. . ”Position Document #1 on Endrin." Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 12 July 1976. . "Pronamide: Position Document 2/3.” Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 15 January 1979. . ”Rotenone: Notice of Completion of Pre-RPAR Review." Federal Register 46, No. 135 (July 15, 1981): p. 36745. . September 1983 Status Report on Rebuttable Pre- sumption Against Registration (RPAR) or Special Review, Registration Standards and the Data Call-In Program. Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Sep- tember 1983. . ”Silvex: Position Document 1/2/3.” washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 9 July 1979. U.S. U.S. van Environmental Protection Agency' Office of Pesticide Programs and Office of Water and Hazardous Materials. ‘5 Benefit-Cost System for Chemical Pesticides. Washing- ton: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, January 1976. House of Representatives Committee on Governmental Operations. Hearings on EPA's Implementation of the Pesticides Control Act. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976. Ravenswaay, Eileen 0. "Political Economics of Regula- tion.” Paper presented to Michigan State University Department of Entomology, East Lansing, MI, 30 October 1980. . “The Science-Policy Interface." PCB's: Human and Environmental Hazards. Edited by Frank D'Itri and Michael Kamrin. Ann Arbor, MI: Ann Arbor Science Pub— lishers, Inc., 1983. and Hull, Beth A. ”Regulatory Decision-Making on Toxic Substances in Food." Paper presented at the Public Choice Society Meetings, New Orleans, LA, March 1981. -306- and Wallace, L. Tim. ”Changing Agricultural Market- ing Programs.” In Federal Marketing Programs in Agri- culture: Issues and Options, pp. 305-326. Edited by Walter J. Armbruster, Dennis Henderson and Ronald D. Knutson. Dansville, IL: The Interstate Printers and Publishers, 1983. Viscusi, W. Kip, and Zeckhauser, Richard J. “Optimal Stan- dards with Incomplete Enforcement.” Public Policy 27, No. 4 (Fall 1979): pp. 437-456. Wade, Larry L. "Economics Applied to Policy Studies.” Policy Studies Journal 2, No. 1 (Autumn 1973): pp. 15-180 Weaver, Paul IL. "Regulation, Social Policy and Class Con- flixH:.' The Public Interest 50 (Winter 1978): pp. 45-63. Wessel, Milton R. Science and Conscience. New York: Colum- bia University Press, 1980. Wilson, James O. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1980, pp. 357-394. Wright, Charles L. 'A Note on the Decision Rules of Public Regulatory Agencies." Public Choice 31 (Fall 1977): pp.