l “w mmzjlfilfllll‘lllll‘“ This is to certify that the dissertation entitled TESTS OF ALTERNATIVE EXCHANGE RATE HYPOTHESES presented by Seth Tobin Kaplan has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Economics Maiflfiéif A/M W m, Major professor Date ' M1 3 l; ”PI/é 0-12771 - A MCI! i. n- An- MSU RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to LIBRARJES remove this checkout from w your record. FINES Will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. TESTS OF ALTERNATIVE EXCHANGE RATE HYPOTHESES BY Seth Tobin Kaplan A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1986 4/0 - 66:”: ABSTRACT TESTS OF ALTERNATIVE EXCHANGE RATE HYPOTHESES By Seth Tobin Kaplan The study is an empirical investigation of the monetary and asset approach to exchange rate determination. A general model which includes monetary, real and portfolio balance effects is formulated and estimated. The model includes p0pular continuous equilibrium and short run disequilibrium exchange rate specifications as restricted cases. Tine alternative exchange rate hypotheses are subjected to four tests. First, the various restrictions imposed on the general model are tested. Second, the stability of the coefficient estimates are examined over several time periods. Third, the competing specifi- cations are subjected to Hausman-wu tests. Fourth, joint tests of model specification and rational expectations are conducted. The model is estimated for the mark-U.S. dollar, Canadian dollar-U.S. dollar, and U.S. dollar-U.K. pound sterling over four sample periods. Although weak evidence is found supporting portfolio balance and real interest rate effects, the results are not robust. Both unrestricted and restricted versions of the general model perform poorly over most samples. Further, the joint test of model specification and rational expectations is rejected in all cases. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to give special thanks to Professor Mordechai Kreinin, chairman of my dissertation comittee, for his invaluable comments and suggestions on this dissertation. I would also like to thank Professor Peter Schmidt for his generous contributions of time and effort regarding the empirical aspects of the thesis. In addition, my thanks go to Professors Robert Rasche and Steven Matusz for also serving on the dissertation committee. I would like to thank several graduate students and friends for encouragement and support during the writing of this thesis. They include Sharon Cisco, Randall Bennett, Rick Rever, Michael Deerfield, and Jack Sayre. I also gratefully acknowledge the fine job of typing the manuscript under a time constraint by Ms. Marilyn "Sam" Miller. Finally, I wish to thank my parents, Leo and Ann Kaplan. Their love, guidance and encouragement is a constant source of strength in my life. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page LIST OF TABLES ................................................ v CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION ...... . ..................................... 1 II. AN OVERVIEW OF MONETARY AND ASSET MODELS ................ 5 2.1 Introduction ....................................... 5 2.2 Precursors to the Monetary/Asset Approach .......... 6 2.3 The Early Monetary Approach .... ....... . ............ 13 2.4 Development of the Monetary/Asset Approach ......... 19 2.5 Testing the Theory ................................. 28 2.6 Conclusion ......................................... 30 Footnotes - Chapter II ..... ............................. 35 III. SOME POPULAR MODELS OF EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION ...... 38 3.1 Introduction ....................................... 38 3.2 Isard's Formulation ............ . ................... 39 3.3 Some Popular Exchange Rate Models .................. 40 3.4 Estimation ......................................... 46 3.5 Results: Summary of Estimation ..................... 49 3.6 Conclusion: Comparison of Alternative Exchange Rate Models ...... ....... . ................. 62 Appendix 3.A. Variable Proxies and Unobservable Variables .................................. 65 Appendix 3.8. Data Sources ............................. 69 Footnotes - Chapter III ..................... . ........... 71 fl iii IV. ESTIMATION OF THE GENERAL MODEL ......................... 73 4.1 Introduction ....................................... 73 4.2 An Econometric Model ............................... 75 4.3 Results: Summary of Estimation 1974:1-1983z3 ....... 80 4.4 Results: Summary of Estimation 1980:2-1984:6 ....... 99 4.5 Summary and Conclusion ............................. 106 Footnotes - Chapter IV .................................. 110 CONCLUSION .............................................. 111 iv LIST OF TABLES Tests of the Monetary/Asset Approaches ..... ........... Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the L0 of Mark/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate, 1974:1- 983:3 coo-eon.ooooeoeoooooooooooooo oooooooooo Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the Log of Mark/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate, 1974:1 :TT978z3 ....................................... Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the L0 of Mark/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate, I978:4 - 983:3 ......... . ........... . ................. Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the L0 of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate,1 :1‘1983:3 0000000000 00.000000000000000 ..... Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the L0 of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate, 1 :1 - 1978:3 .............. ...... . ............ Regressions of the General and Restricted Models on the L0 of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate, 1 :4 - 1983:3 ... ...... . ................ . ...... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Germany-U.S., 1974:1 - 1983:3 .......... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Germany-U.S., 1974:1 - 1978:3 .......... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Germany-U.S., 1978:3 - 1983:3 .......... Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Germany-United States, 1974:1 - 1983:3 ..... Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Germany-United States, 1974:1 - 1978:3 ..... Page 31 52 53 54 58 59 60 82 83 84 86 87 4.15 4.16 Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Germany-United States, 1978:4 - 1983:3 Tests of Rational Expectations Restrictions and FIML Estimates of Coefficients ......... . ..... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Canada-U.S., 1974:1 - 1983:3 ...... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Canada-U.S., 1974:1 - 1978:3 ...... Regressions of Exogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, Canada-U.S., 1978:3 — 1983:3 ...... Regression of Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Canada-United States, 1974:1 - 1983:3 ............ Regression of Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Canada-United States, 1974:1 - 1978:3 ............ Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Canada-United States, 1978:3 - 1983:3 . Germany-United States, 1980:6 - 1984:6 ........... Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Germany-United States, 1980:6 - 1984:6 Canada-United States, 1980:6 - 1984:6 ............ Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, Canada-United States, 1980:6 - 1984:6 . Regression of Endogenous Variables on Their Own Lagged Values, U.K./U.S., 1980:6 - 1984:6 .... Regression of the Unrestricted Reduced Form Equations, U.K./U.S., 1980:6 - 1984:6 .... ........ vi ....... 88 ....... 9O ....... 92 ....... 93 ....... 94 ....... 95 ....... 96 ....... 97 ....... 100 ....... 103 ....... 104 ....... 105 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The last fifteen years has seen a dual revolution in inter- national finance. The collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system in 1973 ushered in an era of floating exchange rates between major national currencies. Over approximately the same period, an equally dramatic shift occurred in balance of payments and exchange rate theory: the monetary/asset approach replaced the components or “account by account" view as the dominant theoretical perspective. While the theoretical foundations of the newer approach appear sound, its empirical validity is an Open question. The purpose of this study is to examine the explanatory power of the monetary/ asset approach during the floating rate era. According to the monetary/asset approach to exchange rate determination, changes in the exchange rate equilibrate the supply and demand for asset stocks denominated in different national currencies. Consequently, long term exchange rate trends reflect the relative growth of asset stocks, in general, and money, in particular. This long-term relationship is often formulated in terms of price levels. Given the first degree homogeneity of money and prices, the exchange rate is expected to reflect the ratio of price levels between countries. Restated, long-term exchange rate trends should tend toward purchasing power parity (PPP). 2 The monetary/asset approach also accounts for highly volatile short-term exchange rate fluctuations. Since most models are formulated with rational expectations, unanticipated changes in asset stocks can drastically effect the exchange rate. This is particularly true of unanticipated permanent changes in asset stock growth rates. The effect of unanticipated shocks on the volatility of exchange movements is exacerbated by "sticky" prices in comedity markets, a common assumption in monetary/asset models. The purpose of this study is twofold. First,“ the eXplanatory power of five p0pular monetary/asset exchange rate models is examined. These include both equilibrium and disequilibrium specifications as well as "pure" monetary and portfolio balance versions. fSecgndI1the~“ validity of the rational expectations assumptionwis,exam1ned, A joint test of the models and rational expectations is conducted. In Chapter II, both the theoretical and empirical literature is reviewed. The review begins with a discussion of the theoretical precussors of the monetary/asset approach: purchasing power parity, interest rate parity and the "Keynesian" flow approach. The discussion proceeds by examining monetary/asset models of greater and ' greater generality. These include the “pure" monetary models of the "Chicago" school, disequilibrium models and finally, models which include terms of trade and portfolio balance effects. The chapter concludes with a discussion of the empirical literature, both estimation techniques and results. In Chapter III, five p0pular monetary/asset models are deveTOped within a cannon framework, the Isard identity. These include the models of Bilson (1978), Frenkel (1976), Dornbush (1976), Frankel 3 (1979), and Hooper and Morton (1980). A general specification which includes the five models as restricted cases, is estimated, using ordinary least-squares (OLS) and instrumental variable (IV) techniques. The U.S. dollar-mark and U.S. dollar-Canadian dollar exchange rates are examined for the period'1973z6-1983z6. The models are compared using four criteria: coefficient sign, coefficient significance, robustness, and model specification. All five models are found to perform poorly. \/' In Chapter IV, a simultaneous equation monetary/asset model is estimated. A, joint “test, of” ”model.--aspec.i..ti.cati.9n“and..."catienaLm Wgfldugtgd. Unrestricted and restricted full information maximum likelihood (FIML) estimates of the equation system form the basis of the tests. The system estimation is preceeded by tests to determine the lag structure for the exogenous variables as well as single equation estimates of model. An additional sample period, 1980:6-1984:6, is included as well as an additional exchange rate, U.S. dollar-U.K. pound sterling. This period covers the monotonic appreciation of the dollar. The relatively “clean“ float of the U.S. dollar-U.K. pound sterling exchange rate precipitated its inclusion. The results of the estimation were generally poor. The joint test of rational expectations and the model were rejected in all cases. 0f the single equation estimates, only the U.S. dollar-mark rate showed mixed results. In Chapter V, the conclusions of the study are discussed. The major contributions of this dissertation lie in its approach to the issue and its conclusions. The study presents a systematic 4 analysis of papular exchange rate models within the monetary/asset approach. The estimated models are subjected to tests of coefficient stability, model specification (Hausman-Nu tests) and joint tests of model specification and rational expectations. The results of these tests confirm the general inadequacy of the monetary/asset approach in providing a robust explanation of exchange rate movements during the post-Bretton Hoods era. CHAPTER II AN OVERVIEW OF MONETARY AND ASSET MODELS 2.1 Introduction The collapse of the Bretton Hood system in 1973, coupled with advances in closed economy macroeconomic theory, led to a resurgence of interest in international finance in general and exchange rate determination in particular. The new models differed significantly from the Keynesian approach prevalent during the early post-World War 11 period. Specifically, exchange rate equilibrium is defined in terms of asset stocks rather than commodity flows. Moreover, general equilibrium models replace the earlier "account by account" partial equilibrium analysis. This chapter traces the development of monetary and asset models of exchange rate determination during the last fifteen years. The models will be presented according to criteria of theoretical similarity and generality with the least general models examined first. Section 2.2 examines the precursors to the monetary and asset models. Recent developments in exchange rate theory can be viewed as attempts to integrate the early approaches into models predicated on stock equilibrimm. Three different approaches will be summarized as each motivated different aspects of the monetary/asset models. First, the purchasing power parity approach (PPP) will be examined. Many of 6 the floating exchange rate models define PPP as an equilibrium condition. Second, the interest rate parity condition is defined and explored. Interest rate parity, sometimes in conjunction with PPP, is often used to explain equilibrium and disequilibrium adjustment in monetary/asset floating rate models. Finally, aspects of the Keynesian flow model will be considered. The emphasis of the current account in Keynesian models was temporarily abandoned in monetary/ asset exchange rate models. It has, however, been reincorporated into the stock models as a mechanism to transfer wealth and limit divergence from equilibrium. Section 2.3 traces the develOpment of early monetary models. Special attention will be focused upon the assumptions of the monetary approach and its divergence from the Keynesian flow model. The origins of the model will also be explored. Section 2.4 continues the discussion of the monetary/asset approach by considering models of greater generality. Five extensions are discussed: 1) expectations, 2) currency substitution, 3) devia- tions from equilibrium, 4) real effects, and 5) wealth effects. The relationship between the newer models and the approaches in Section 2.2 will be examined. A summary of the empirical literature which examines both econometric technique and results appears in Section 2.5. Section 2.6 offers a brief conclusion. 2.2 Precursors to the Monetary/Asset Approach 1 A. Purchasing Power Parity. At the core of all purchasing power parity (PPP) variants lies the contention that the exchange rate between two national currencies reflects the ratio of prices in the 7 countries of denomination. This relationship can be formulated in two ways: absolute PPP and relative PPP. The former holds that the exchange rate is equal to the ratio of price levels in the two countries. The latter postulates that the exchange rate is a constant multiple of the ratio of price indexes. Due to the dearth of price level data relative PPP is often the only testable hypothesis.2 PPP is not an economic theory: it offers no explanation of the relationship it posits. Rather, it is an equilibrium condition arising from several different theoretical formulations of the international market mechanism. Each explanation of market behavior gives rise to a different variant of PPP using different price indexes to describe equilibrium (see below). Further, each view of market behavior suggests the possibility of deviation from PPP and the length of the adjustment process. The theoretical foundations of PPP can be traced to four different types of international arbitrage. Each form of arbitrage yields an apprOpriate price index ratio in which to state PPP equili- brium while explaining both deviation and adjustment to PPP. The first form of PPP suggests the use of general price indexes and contends that commodity arbitrage will ensure one price in unobstructed international markets. A second version makes the distinction between tradable and non-tradable goods. PPP is still formulated with general price indexes when assuming the relative price of tradables and non-tradables remain constant. However, if this assumption is drOpped, PPP needs to be reformulated using import/ export price indexes. 8 Another version of PPP is based on the mobility of factors of production rather than the mobility of commodities. Deviations from PPP are corrected by the movement of labor and capital in uncontrolled international markets. PPP is then formulated using cost of produc- tion indexes. Finally, PPP can be derived. from the relationship between exchange rate and price level expectations. It has been argued that arbitrage in the international asset markets ensures that the eXpected 3 It is exchange rate equals the ratio of expected price levels. further claimed that changes in the observed values parallel those of expected values. Thus, PPP holds as a proximate condition. General price levels are used in formulating this theoretical construction. Empirical evidence suggests that PPP does not hold continuously and, therefore, does not present an adequate explanation of short-run exchange rate fluctuations.‘4 Clearly, influences other than general price levels can precipitate short-run exchange rate movements. This suggests that models which employ PPP are generally in disequilibrium when estimated in the short run. The validity of PPP in the long run is open to question. It is unclear whether portfolio balance and real effects have a systematic influence on the long run equilibrium exchange rate. During periods of extreme price instability PPP appears to offer the most adequate 5 explanation of exchange rate movement. It is, however, uncertain whether this is due to the validity of PPP or the shear magnitude of the price effect. 6 8. Interest Rate Parity and Interest Rate Arbitrage. Interest rate parity (IRP) is an equilibrium condition which equates the 9 return, expressed in domestic currency, of domestic and foreign assets.7 Equilibrium is maintained by arbitraguers acting in the asset and forward exchange markets. As such, IRP provides the theoretical foundation for the uncovered and covered interest arbitrage schedules. The IRP condition connects domestic and foreign asset markets with spot and forward exchange markets. Consider a two period, two asset world in which domestic and foreign assets earn rates of interest r and r*, respectively. The assets mature in period two. A domestic investor, with endowment A, will receive A(1+r) in period two by purchasing domestic assets in period one. Alternatively, he can guarantee his domestic currency return on foreign investment by simultaneously: 1) converting endowment A into foreign currency at the spot exchange rate, 5 (expressed as foreign currency per unit of domestic currency), 2) purchasing A-s worth of foreign assets, and 3) contracting to sell A-s(1+r*) of foreign currency at forward rate, f. The second period domestic currency accumulation on foreign investment is Avs(1+r*)/f. Equating the accumulations and rearranging terms yields the IRP condition: (f-s)/s=r*-r. Deviations from IRP are corrected by arbitraguers. The analysis can be expanded by assuming the actions of a 8 The speculator buys or sells forward currency if the expected future spot rate, se, differs from the forward rate. The speculator. difference between the rates is a risk premium attributable to portfolio balance considerations: f=se-risk (Solnik, 1974; Dornbush, 1980). Substituting the previous expression into the IRP condition yields (Se-s)/s=r*-r-risk, the covered interest arbitrage schedule. A 10 zero risk premium implies uncovered interest arbitrage. Both schedules are used extensively in models of exchange rate deter- mination. Test of the empirical validity of IRP and interest rate arbitrage has given rise to an extensive literature. Attention has focused on three questions: 1) Does IRP hold continuously, 2) Is the forward rate an unbiased estimate of the future spot rate, and 3) Is the forward rate an efficient estimate of the future spot rate? The first question can be answered in the affirmative. The weight of evidence suggests IRP holds continuously in Eurocurrency markets.9 Evidence suggesting deviations from IRP use asset markets that are not fully integrated. This is the case when domestic and foreign Treasury bond yields are substituted for Eurocurrency rates. The second and third questions remain unanswered. The forward rate appears unbiased over periods in which the exchange rate both appreciates and depreciates. However, the forward rate consistently underestimates the volitility of the spot rate. The question of forward market efficiency also remains unanswered. It should be noted, however, that a non-zero risk premium does not imply bias. C. The Components Approach. The income/elasticity approach was the dominant view of balance-of-payments and exchange rate determi- nation during the Bretton Woods era. The approach is a synthesis of Keynesian Open economy national income determination and devaluation analysis associated with Marshall, Lerner and others.10 According to the most papular versions of the elasticity approach, equilibrium is defined as either a zero trade balance or current account balance. Movements of the current account are 11 considered responses to underlying economic fundamentals while the capital account plays an accommodating role by financing the decisions made on the "real" part of the balance-of-payments statement. Thus, sole emphasis is placed on imports and exports while capital flows are all but ignored. The income approach emphasizes the relationship between the equilibrium level of national income and the balance of trade. Autonomous increases in expenditures move the trade balance toward deficit by increasing the flow of imports. The result is due to the income elasticity of imports or marginal propensity to import specified in Keynesian type models. Although both approaches were originally constructed to analyze fixed and pegged exchange rate regimes, they can be reformulated to examine the floating rate case. The exchange rate, once exogenous, becomes endogenous. However, the fundamental results of the models remain unchanged. Consider a shift toward current account deficit caused by a change in preference toward imported goods. The elasticity approach suggests that equilibrium on the current account is restored by a change in the relative price (i.e. terms of trade) of imports. This is accomplished by a depreciation in the exchange rate resulting in a deterioration in the terms of trade. The value of eXports would 11 The increase relative to imports and move to restore equilibriwm. central result of the elasticity approach, given a movement toward current account deficit, is the ceteris paribus depreciation of the exchange rate. 12 The income approach posits a direct relationship between income and the exchange rate. An exogenous increase in income raises the demand for imports via the marginal propensity to import. The increase in demand for foreign goods is translated into an increased demand for foreign exchange. This, in turn, depreciates the exchange rate expressed in terms of domestic currency and dampens or reverses the process. A simple merging of the income and elasticity approaches into a single equation model yields the result most commonly associated with flow models of the Bretton Woods era: exogenous increases in domestic income cw" exogenous movements of the current account toward deficit are associated with depreciation of the exchange rate. An additional result, the effect of interest rate changes, is develOped from separate analysis of the capital account. Exogenous increases in the domestic interest rate lead to increased demand for domestic currency and, therefore, exchange rate appreciation. Although the Keynesian flow approach is often characterized by a single equation model with determinate signs for the exogenous variables, several qualifications are in order. First, the separate theoretical relationships of the exchange rate with income, interest rates and the current account are derived from partial equilibrium analysis. Second, the exogeneity requirements imposed by a single equation model violate the clear interaction of the variables. This is evident when considering the current account and income: increases in income raise imports and move the current account towards deficit. The single equation model should not be confused with a general equilibrium analysis. 13 2.3 The Early Monetary Approach Advocates of the monetary approach claim the supply and demand of money stocks are the primary determinates of equilibrium in open macroeconomic systems. The approach encompasses both balance of payments analysis under fixed exchange rate regimes and exchange rate determination in floating rate regimes. Several characteristics of the monetary approach distinguish it from other theories. First, monetary models define equilibrium in stocks rather than flows. Second, the balance-of—payments is analyzed in tgtgm_rather than account by account. Third, the effects of real variables are generally transmitted through the arguments of the money demand equation rather than directly. Fburth, the exchange rate is considered the relative price of currencies rather than the relative price of domestic and foreign goods. These characteristics lead to conclusions radically different than earlier partial equilibrium approaches. Elements of the monetary approach appear as early as the sixteenth century in Sweden where it was argued that increases in the money stock depreciate the currency.12 This argument was repeated in the U.K. bullionist controversy. The fixed rate analogy, that increases in the money supply cause balance-of—payments deficit, was suggested by several economists including Keynes. Other aspects of the monetary approach appear throughout the classical literature.13 The modern interpretation and formalization of the monetary 14 For a variety of approach began at the International Monetary Fund. practical and theoretical considerations, the monetary approach became a prime instrument for policy analysis. However, it was not until the 14 late 1960's that the monetary approach entered the academic mainstream through the work of Mundell and Johnson.15 An analysis of money market adjustment is the central emphasis of both the fixed and floating exchange rate versions of the monetary approach. Development of either version begins by specifying a money demand equation. The specification of choice, Md=Pf(y,r), states the demand for nominal money balances, Md, equals the product of the price level, P, with a function (f) of real income, y, and the nominal interest rate, r. This conventional specification assumes the demand for money is directly related to real income, inversely related to the interest rate, homogeneous to degree one with respect to the price level and relatively stable over time. The analysis is continued by specifying the supply of money and clearing the market. The nominal supply of money, MS, equals the money multiplier, m, times the foreign, R, and domestic, 0, components of the monetary base: Ms=m(R+D). Setting money supply equal to money demand yields: m(R+D)=Pf(y,r). This equation is the foundation for the fixed exchange rate case of the monetary approach. The model is completed by specifying the price income and interest rate variables. The global monetarists assume the following: first, real income is exogenous due to long run full employment and, second, the price level and interest rate are exogenous due to the law of one price in both commodity and capital markets. The exogeneity of prices and interest rates can also be explained by the small country assumption without reference to the law of one price. Examination of the fully Specified money market equation shows that balance of payments disequilibriwm, R, is directly attributable 15 to changes in either the domestic component Of the monetary base or the demand for MONEY! mAR=AIPf(V.r)]-mAD.16 Balance Of payment flows continue until adjustment in the money market is complete and stock equilibrium is restored. Consider an Open market operation which increases the domestic component Of the monetary base. This creates an excess stock supply Of money. The demand side exogeneity assumptions allow only one channel for adjustment: changes in the foreign component Of the monetary base. Thus, money market adjustment is associated with balance Of payments' surplus and deficit. It follows directly that the stock supply Of money is endogenous in fixed rate versions Of the monetary approach. Changes in the domestic component Of the monetary base are met by equal and Opposite changes in the foreign component. Barring sterilization, government authorities control the composition Of the money supply, but have no control over its level.17 The endogeneity Of the money supply is also apparent when changes in money demand are examined. Increases in either the price level or real income increase the stock demand for money. Without changes in domestic credit, the only source Of funds is from abroad. Thus, both increased price and income levels create a temporary balance Of payments' surplus as the foreign component Of the monetary base expands. The process continues until stock equilibrium is restored. Conversely, an increase in the interest rate creates an excess supply Of money. Decreases in foreign reserves are necessary to restore money market equilibrium. Thus, a higher interest rate is associated with a balance Of payments deficit. 16 Two aspects Of monetary balance Of payments analysis should be emphasized. First, changes in the demand for money and the domestic component Of the monetary base create balance Of payments disequi- librium: the causation is unidirectional. Second, the composition Of temporary balance Of payment flows is irrelevant: the monetary approach does not distinguish between the current and capital accounts. The second point accounts for the apparent contradiction between the monetary and component account approaches. Keynesian analysis predicts a current account deficit following an increase in real income and a capital account surplus following an increase in the interest rate. As shown above, the monetary approach predicts a balance Of payment surplus in the former and a deficit in the latter. The conflicting results derive from the ceteris paribus assumptions present in a "component account" partial equilibrium analysis. B. The Floating Rate Case. While the modern revivers Of the monetary approach suggest it is applicable to both fixed and floating exchange rate regimes, development Of monetary exchange rate models lagged behind their balance Of payments counterparts. This situation was remedied by the collapse Of the Bretton Woods system and the advent Of floating rates. The focus Of theoretical attention shifted towards models Of exchange rate determination. The first major difference between floating rate and fixed rate models stems directly from exchange rate endogeneity. Both moneta- rists and nonmonetarists would agree that a freely floating exchange rate clears the foreign exchange market. This implies continuous balance Of payments equilibrium, or, equivalently, no changes in the 17 foreign component of the monetary base. Consequently, a floating exchange rate implies nominal money supply exogeneity. The second major difference between fixed and floating rate regimes is the method Of adjustment toward equilibrium. In the fixed rate case, changes in the foreign component of the monetary base act to equilibrate the money market by changing the nominal money stock. The exogenous price level assured adjustment between the real money stock and the demand for real balances. In the floating rate case, the exogeneity Of the money stock forces adjustment through the price level and, consequently, the exchange rate. These and other aspects Of the monetary approach to exchange rate determination are best examined with reference to a simply specified model. The money markets Of the two countries can be described by conventional money demand equations and exogenous money supplies. Assuming both markets clear: (1) M = Pf(y,r) (2) M* = P*f(y*,r*) where "*" denotes foreign country variables. The model is completed by assuming PPP (s = P/P*), solving the money markets for prices, and substituting: (3) s = Mf(y*,r*)/M*f(y,r) As iri the fixed rate case, the exchange rate is determined by money market conditions in the two countries. Changes in income and interest rates associated with a surplus/deficit in the fixed rate case are associated with an appreciation/depreciation in the floating rate case. Consider an exogenous increase in income. This increases the stock demand for money and creates an incipient balance Of 18 payments surplus. Under fixed rates an actual surplus ensues through an increase in the foreign component Of the money supply. Under floating rates a decrease in the price level raises real balances and restores money market equilibrium. Falling domestic prices simultaneously appreciate the currency through PPP. Increases in the money supply or interest rate precipitate a depreciation by effecting an incipient balance of payments deficit. The preceding model assumes that PPP holds continuously, and the exchange rate is determined soley by present values Of arguments in the money market equations. This implies that equation (3) is: 1) valid as both a short and long run explanation Of exchange rate determination, and 2) equivalent to a fully specified general equilibrium model including all aspects of the components approach.18 Excess supply/demand for money is instantaneously balanced by excess demand/supply Of gOOds and nonmonetary assets. Several criticisms, however, have been leveled at this specifi- cation Of the monetary approach. The first criticism cites the lack Of attention paid to nonmonetary asset markets. The assumption Of interest rate exogeneity in a ffloating rate world seems very strong indeed.19 The second criticism is leveled at the PPP assumption. Critics have cited two different Objections. The first group Of Observers accepts PPP as a long run condition but rejects instan- taneous price adjustment. This leads to short run deviations from PPP in the context Of disequilibrium adjustment. A second group rejects PPP as a statement describing the exchange rate and general price levels in both the short and long run. They agree that the relative price Of tradable goods will reflect the exchange rate, but there is 19 no necessary reason to expect nontraded goods to meet that condition. If this were the case, the exchange rate will generally ngt_reflect the ratio of absolute price levels. 2.4 DevelOpment Of the Monetary/Asset Approach This section reviews the development Of monetary exchange rate models. The develOpment can be viewed as a process in which the strict assumptions Of the simple model are relaxed. Although the exchange rate is always viewed in the context Of stock equilibrium, its determination is characterized by factors not present in the simple specification. The factors which determine the exchange rate are: 1) the money, asset and goods market specifications, 2) the restrictions imposed on the models solution, and 3) the mechanism for dynamic adjustment (in models which allow deviations from equilibrium). The monetary approach to exchange rate determination has evolved through the develOpment Of these factors and their determinants. The discussion will proceed by examining five extensions of the simple model. While they are Often combined in particular exchange rate models, each extension creates a new factor which influences the exchange rate. First, expectations are introduced by examining the asset market in the context Of continuous PPP. Second, currency substitution models are developed by allowing residents to demand both domestic and foreign monies. Third, asset and commodity markets are examined under conditions of short run disequilibrium. Fourth, the effects Of relative price changes are explored by the introduction Of two or more goods. Fifth, portfolio balance models are considered, and the effects Of wealth shifts and risk are explicitly examined. 20 A. Expectations. While the assumptions Of our simple model assure the equality Of real interest rates, the relationship between nominal interest rates and the exchange rate is not fully specified. Two alternative yet complimentary approaches have been used to close the models: the first introduces IRP, while the second introduces Fisher equations. Both invoke rational expectations. According to IRP, the nominal interest rate differential reflects the lgg_difference between the forward and spot rates. The forward rate, in turn, can be made endogenous by assuming the uncovered interest arbitrage condition: the forward rate equals the expected future spot rate. By performing these substitutions in the simple model, the exchange rate is seen as a function Of money supplies, incomes and the expected spot rate. The analysis is completed by invoking rational expectations and modeling the expected spot rate using expected future values Of the exogenous variables.20 The exchange rate and interest rates were directly linked using IRP; Fisher equations link them indirectly through PPP. Since real interest rates are assumed equal across countries, nominal interest rate differentials can be attributed to differing levels Of inflation expectations. The exchange rate, as.a ratio Of two price levels, is now determined by money supplies, incomes and inflation expectations. By invoking rational expectations, inflation expectations are shown tO be determined in the money market according to expected future values Of the exogenous variables. Thus, the IRP and Fisher equation approaches are equivalent in the simple model with continuous PPP equilibrium.21 21 The use of rational expectations changes the character Of the exchange rate solution. In particular, the exchange rate depends upon both current and expected future values Of the exogenous variables as well as the interest elasticity Of the demand for money.22 B. Currency Substitution. Models of currency substitution extend the standard monetary model by allowing residents to hold both domestic and foreign currencies. The composition Of the currency portfolio is determined by expected rates Of return. The differential expected rate Of return equals the rate Of depreciation for noninterest earning assets. Two variants Of currency substitution models exist in the literature. The global monetarist models generally assume integrated 23 A second variant capital markets, one gOOd, and two countries. analyzes a small country, twO good model in the absence of capital flows.24 Changes in the supply Of foreign currency occur through the current account. Models Of the second variety will be examined at a later point in the discussion. Global monetarist currency substitution models define the exchange rate as a function Of money supplies and relative holding costs Of domestic and foreign currencies. This is evident when the money demand specifications are considered. The transaction demand for domestic money is determined by the sum Of domestic and foreign income; the same is true for foreign currency.25 Further, real money stocks are expressed in terms Of domestic prices in both countries tO avoid the PPP condition. The exchange rate, as a ratio of money market equations, is determined by relative money supplies and the interest rate differential. | 22 Assuming uncovered interest arbitrage, the nominal interest differential equals the expected rate Of depreciation (i.e. the expected future rate minus the spot rate). Imposing rational expectations yields an expression for the exchange rate which includes current and expected future values Of exogenous variables adjusted by a parameter which measures the elasticity Of substitution between currencies.26 The currency substitution model views the exchange rate as an asset price which equilibrates the holding cost Of currencies. If currency substitution is not perfect, an interest rate differential or expected depreciation can exist. However, in the case Of perfect substitution, interest rates must be equal or one currency will be driven from circulation: no investor would hold a currency expected to depreciate (in the absence Of risk). C. Disequilibrium. Thus far, innovations in exogenous variables led to instantaneous adjustment in both the asset and goods market. The exchange rate, therefore, is in constant equilibrium. Models Of exchange rate disequilibrium break from these assumptions. The exchange rate deviates from its equilibrium level as a consequence Of slowly adjusting markets. Dynamic models, then, are concerned with both the equilibrium path and adjustment to that path. The distinction between the behavior Of asset prices and commodity prices is central to dynamic disequilibrium models.27 while asset prices adjust quickly tO information effecting their current and future value, commodity prices often respond slowly. This results in exchange market disequilibrium. 23 Consider a simple one gOOd two country monetary model with rational expectations where the equilibrium exchange rate is defined by PPP.28 Assume that current or future changes in the exogenous variables are not expected. Given equilibrium, this implies real interest rates are equal (in a world Of perfect capital mobility), and inflation rates are zero. Consider an unanticipated one time decrease in the domestic money supply. An immediate appreciation of the equilibrium exchange rate is needed to restore money market equilibrium. If this is accompanied by an instantaneous proportional decrease in the domestic price level, equilibrium PPP would hold continuously. If, however, domestic commodity prices are slow to adjust, equilibrium PPP is not immediately restored. When output prices are sticky, the decrease in real balances (caused by the decrease in the domestic money supply) raises the domestic cost Of capital or real interest rate. This implies a real interest rate differential between home and abroad. The differential, in turn, creates a forward premium on domestic currency (IRP) equal to the expected depreciation (rational expectations). As commodity prices adjust to the new money supply, the exchange rate continues to depreciate and the interest rate differential narrows. Equilibrium PPP is restored once prices fully adjust.29 Two aspects Of the preceding analysis should be noted. First, equilibrimn and disequilibrimm exchange rate paths are determined by the price adjustment specification. In the above example, the implicit price mechanism caused the exchange rate to overshoot its 3D equilibrium level. A general specification describes both the 24 equilibrium and disequilibrium price path. Price adjusts to expected changes in its equilibrium value and to goods market disequilibrium.31 Second, the disequilibrium model can change the interpretation Of the nominal interest rate differential. In models Of continuous equilibrium the differential represents differing inflation (expec- tations. However, in disequilibrium models, nominal differentials can be associated with real differentials. The exchange rate depreciates in the former case but appreciates in the latter. 0. Several Goods. The notion that the terms-Of-trade (TOT) influence the exchange rate has a long history in international finance. The elasticity approach views the TOT as the central mechanism in balance-of—payments adjustment. Change in relative rather than absolute prices play the key role. The extension Of the monetary approach to two goods Opens new avenues for exchange rate determination. First, real effects are allowed channels Of causation other than the income term Of the money demand equation. Second, the addition Of relative prices allow deviations from PPP in both equilibrium and disequilibrium specifications. Third, the current account can play an explicit role in exchange rate adjustment. Consider a two country, two good model with complete speciali- zation in production. The TOT is defined as the relative price Of the domestic good in terms of the foreign good. Movements in the TOT can occur through changes in the ratio Of domestic and foreign good prices and/or the exchange rate. The homogeneity properties Of prices and the exchange rate with respect to money preclude permanent TOT Inovements associated with changes in nominal money stocks. However, 25 real changes in the supply and demand for goods will effect the equilibrium TOT. Assume an increase in foreign demand for domestic output. This would, ceteris paribus, increase the ratio Of domestic to foreign prices. It would also increase the demand for domestic currency as foreigners attempt to substitute goods from abroad for those produced at home. Thus, an increase in the terms Of trade appreciates the exchange rate. Further, the appreciation is associated with deviations from PPP: the exchange rate which equalizes the balance Of trade increases relative to PPP. Finally, this result Obtains in conditions Of continuous equilibrium.32 Slowly adjusting prices create another source Of PPP deviatiOns in two good dynamic models. However, these are disequilibrium phenomena when the equilibrium TOT is fixed.33 Consider an exogenous shock which increases the equilibrium general price level while leaving the equilibrium 'TOT unchanged. Equal increases in the general price level and the exchange rate will occur in the long run. However, short run disequilibrium will ensue when the price Of domestic goods are "sticky." The shock creates an excess supply Of money which drives down the domestic interest rate (if real balances remain constant). This depreciates the exchange rate. The TOT deteriorate since the depreciation is not accompanied by rising domestic good prices. Consequently, general price levels no longer reflect PPP in the short run. The adjustment process in a two gOOd model parallels model adjustment in a one good model with one major difference. Slowly increasing domestic prices increase the TOT and consequently the 26 general price level. The exchange rate appreciates and the interest rate increase until equilibrium is restored. The exchange rate and TOT move together in both equilibrium and disequilibrium adjustment. According to the income and absorption approaches the current account plays an important role in equilibrating the exchange rate. In fact, exchange rate equilibrium is defined as a zero current account. Some dynamic disequilibrium monetary models have incorporated the effects Of current account imbalances.34 As in the previous analysis, the asset market determines the exchange rate. It is the current account, however, that determines the path. In particular, the income from fOreign assets enters the money demand function. Moreover, the real value Of external assets held by residents is a determinate Of domestic wealth. Finally, wealth and the terms Of trade are arguments in the demand for domestic goods. The solution to the model demonstrates that only one level of wealth will clear the money and good markets given the relationship between the equilibrium TOT and external assets held by domestic residents. Below this level Of wealth assets are accumulated creating a current account surplus. The increase in wealth associated with the surplus increases the demand for domestic goods and improves the TOT. With foreign prices fixed, the current account surplus is associated with an exchange rate appreciation. E. Portfolio Balance Effects35. Thus far, the forward exchange rate has been identified with the expected future spot rate. Given IRP, this implies outside bonds denominated in different currencies 27 are perfect substitutes. Further, it implicitly assumes that bondholders are risk neutral. Models Of portfolio-balance eliminate these restrictive assumptions. Investors attempt to maximize the utility from their portfolio, subject tO their perception Of risk, by equalizing expected asset yields. Given domestic and foreign interest rates, expected yields are equalized by the expected rate Of appreciation. In a risk averse environment, expected yields are effected by the excess Of supply Of bonds.36 Assume a forward premium on domestic currency. If the supply Of bonds denominated in domestic currency increased, ceteris paribus, investors would demand a higher expected rate of return to willingly accept them into their portfolios. At existing interest rates, a risk premium, above the forward premium, is needed to clear the asset market. The expected future spot rate would then exceed the forward rate. The risk premium is also sensitive to the international distribution Of wealth if domestic and foreign residents differ in their perceptions Of risk. A transfer Of wealth from home to abroad will increase the risk premium if domestic residents have a relative preference for assets denominated in domestic currency. The excess supply Of bonds created by the transfer requires an increase in the expected rate Of appreciation to clear the asset market. TO sunlnarize, either increases in the relative supply Of bonds denominated in domestic currency or transfers Of wealth abroad, ceteris paribus, raise the risk premium on domestic currency. This severs the expected future spot rate - forward rate identity. 28 Finally, the current account has been reestablished as an important mechanism in achieving exchange rate equilibrium. 'The wealth effect generated by current account flows influences the exchange rate in two ways. First, an increase in wealth causes a relative price effect by raising the demand for domestic output in two good models. Second, the wealth effect precipitates a rebalancing Of portfolios. 2.5 Testing The Theory This section overviews the estimation procedures employed in testing the monetary/asset approach to exchange rate determination. A general description Of single equation and systems techniques will be examined. A discussion Of proxy variables is also included. One group Of studies uses single equation techniques tO test the sign and significance Of exogenous variable coefficients. Studies Of this variety have grown to include all the theoretical effects described earlier in the chapter; although, many employ only a subset. As a general specification, the exchange rate is estimated as a func- tion Of money supplies, incomes, interest rates, expected inflation, real effects, and risk. While the proxies for monies, incomes and interest rates have conventional interpretations, the other variables present modeling problems since they are unobservable. Because Of this, the expected inflation rate has been proxied in several different ways. First, long term interest rate differentials or long term forward rate premiwms have been substituted for expected inflation differentials. This will yield unbiased estimates if the Fisher equation is assumed, real interest rates are equal, and there is coefficient equality 29 across countries. A second alternative employes an adaptive mechanism )/// to predict future inflation. A six or twelve month moving average Of \PTA past inflation rates is generally used. The risk term has also found several proxies: the supply Of government bonds, the supply Of foreign bonds held by residents, current account statistics, and complete specifications. The first proxy attempts tO capture changes in risk associated with relative changes in the supply Of outside assets. The second and third proxies capture change in risk associated with changes in the residence of wealth. Finally, the general specifications attempt tO capture both effects. Real effects, exchange rate movements due to changes in supply and demand for domestic and foreign goods, are proxied in two ways. First, relative import and export price ratios are used. This proxy attempts tO distinguish between relative and absolute price changes. Second, either current account or trade statistics are employed in an attempt to capture supply and demand changes. An extension Of this technique uses unexpected changes in the current account or trade balance to model real effects. The expected balance is calculated! g51flg_a_mmxing_31££igg_n£99§SS»WMDeMiationsmfrnmwtheflexpecteg“!alue_w ~9.rg_.1'-hen-—r-89Fessedeonwtbesexghenflgmrefiee A second group Of empirical studies explicitly accounts for the rational expectation assumption present in most theoretical models. V/The stochastic processes Of exogenous variables are eiifl§£_2§§!fl§fl“2£,. W Estimates Of the general exchange rate model include a joint test Of the model and the rational expectations assumption. 30 In this type Of procedure, the expectational variables are no longer proxied. Rather, the solution Of the model determines the exchange rate as a function Of present, past and expected future changes in the exogenous variables. Consider, for example, the simple monetary model. The interest rate differential or expected depreciation is a function Of past, present, and expected future values of monies and incomes. Table 2.1 reviews the empirical exchange rate studies Of the monetary/asset approach since 1978.37 The studies which employ FIML or maximum likelihood estimation test for rational expectations as well as model specification. The conclusions drawn in the "results" column are my own and may not necessarily agree with the author(s) Of the study. "Positive" results imply significance Of all exogenous variables. 2.6 Conclusion The monetary/asset approach has become the dominant theoretical explanation Of exchange rate determination. The approach differs from its immediate predecessors by defining equilibrium in terms of stocks rather than flows. Further, the approach is a general equilibrium formulation as Opposed tO earlier account-by-account analysis. The historical development Of the monetary/asset approach can be viewed as a series of extensions Of the simple monetary model. Specifically, general formulations Of the bond and goods markets allow for stock/flow interaction to determine the exchange rate and its path. The specification Of various price adjustment mechanisms determine both the equilibrium and disequilibrium behavior Of the exchange rate. 31 mam .g=\oue..a ma: .moo m m~-~ SN .m=\aueeea ..c-e. ..x .» ..e .e we Aeemu. e.oeouu~: «an m=\eeaaa cox.z .mso NH as- ”me .m=\g= .ee-e. .4» .x ..e .e we Aemmav e_e=eeoez o>_uuomuo m: ee. m: e».: .eca» -e__e .g: .m: .mm.zm .ee._ceeuoz .conoa .»_eu~ .Loe eox.x moo H“ as-” me .ca .eeu .L-L..»-x..e.e m.“ .emmfi. puapp.z eea eeex .eceaee. . . .a ”<9 moa Sz_a EH um-~H me Law a L «a: .a a» m Remaa. .Peem_=-_poee=pm ‘8 a» ah oh 0: Lo H..m . ualrea=..ae=i=. Jere....».é.7...._.._..r...._. me: moo >~Homm~--~”-aa eau\m= ea ..e-e...ec-e....x-»....e.u. a .emma. museum g=\m= .ed\m= nee used Ndumsaa-e «emu Loo\m= .sq.»<..eq.nq..».»..e.e a .nmofi. use:~me.eum a ensecoz mupamoa oacvcguo» covcom oewh mupcucaou mopaapgo> ovum xvsum u accuses—nxu aco>opo¢ oncoguxu mm=u¢Hnms-auune H..e-.e.-.e-evg cox.z .moo e as-“ me m: ..x-»v..e-a. m .ommu. eoucoz a canoe: mumN eaxez .moo m we-m SA Loa\m= ea.a..z.: a .aema. ..e no eomeeem mumN eax_z .moo NH e~-m as Loo\m= .a.d..z.: m .Ahmfiv ..e be eomeeco >~ A‘hrI—pvnACi-ILV a‘EIEVIW eax_z .moo N QN-N «A m=\eou ...»-x....s.s. .m .msaa. .oxeoca . «5.5.1.35 .iLQ.LQ..—IA>Q\IV.AIm eox.: moo NA om-~ ”A g: ~-H...-L.-,.e-e.u.~-.c-e. m Emma”. eeue.,.a no; a: «A e.aea.eoe .a-»..c-e..s.u m “mead. __oa.a no; oz~a e“ am-” «A Loc\m= us.» .d-..u.ev..e.a. m .mmad. co: anamuraiav Athlaaliafilld aafil‘Fthv flit .HIIF .fik .HIL >~ d0¥L ovum xvaum » meouocapnxm aco>opo¢ mocazuxu goose—ucouv ~.N open» 33 .o. acomoea op co,»e_oc :_ uovcoa ouocou munpeumaam . a- copeoa awe. not» omcocu . ea: mpnuvco> cmpocob .nslaae ovum; o>comoe uog.:¢oc--ns-amm sup; omcozuxo r‘ xmvm - i a wagon acoscco>om mo »_aa:m : m unsouuu acoceau - <0 oucopon once» u m» mzucoe o» Loewe m_ueoe=c O_nmce =u_x muovcaa as.» meoucoaa a» some; m_ucoe:= coeom gap: muoveoa we,» . » covuapmcp vouuoaxo . e po>op woven u—Lox on» we oop . 3n po>op woven on» we mop . one; unocuu=. ugaaEOJ custom - can; umocouc. stop «seem - oaou=_ poo; 50 no, u »_nn:m xocoe as» we mop . one; omensuxo o>puuoumo on» go mop . muse omcazuxo on» we mo. u L » ucoeov hence no mop . z e m m m—oaexm on aux coo\m= conua\m: umh.mh..«=-=. max gum e do-” me x=\m= .Ave-c..,.x-»....e-e. .Nmmav ccoaoz a «ago: me: :ozw m ow-nuns m=\eau «a..c.».e m .Nmmd. coemme_a woe moo No as-" me Law 3.“ ...a-a..a-~ “-.a .M-» ..» .x no: .muo N ow-e NA g: .e . e ..e .e «Q .m gamma. eeoexoe a undue: mom used _~"~w--"ne __~ecm xaau .ezqu .oae .a-a_ mom .moo Nauom-~”.~ m=\coe «e.e...c-e...».»..u.e a .Hmmfl. paxeeca 4 om-~ «A . ovum xvaum xuouacupaxu acu>opua macesoxm .voacpucou. ~.~ u—aap 34 Tests Of the monetary/asset approach are, thus far, inconclusive. It appears, however, that results are very sensitive to both the choice Of countries and the time period. This could be the result Of unstable money demand equations or changing asset preferences. Alter- nately, the model could be misspecified. 35 FOOTNOTES - CHAPTER II 1For a review Of the PPP literature, see Officer (1976) and Officer (1984). 2The formulation Of absolute PPP requires weights to constrict price levels. This poses major difficulties. See Officer (1984). 3This relationship is Often posited in the monetary approach. 4 tests. 5The post World War I German hyperinflation is a case in point. See Frenkel, 1976. 6For a review of the pre-1970 IRP literature, see Officer and Willett (1970). 7 See Kreinin and Officer (1978) for references to empirical The development Of IRP begins with Keynes (1923). 8See, for example, Aliber (1973). 9See Marston (1976) and Herring and Marston (1976). 10Many consider Harberger (1950) as the classic article. 11We assume the Marshall-Lerner conditions tO hold. 12See Myhrman (1976) for a discussion Of the Swedish debate. 13The roots Of the monetary approach are examined in Frenkel (1976), Frenkel and Johnson (1976) and Kreinin and Officer (1978). 14Studies Of the monetary approach originated at the IMF are collected in International Monetary Fund (1977). 15The works of Mundell (1968, 1971), Johnson (1972) and Komiya (1969) are generally credited for introducing the monetary approach to the academic establishment. 16This assumes the money multiplier, m, is constant. 17Sterlization is generally assumed away in early monetary models. See, for example, Magee (1976). 36 18This fact is recognized by many authors including Bilson (1979) and Isard (1978). 19Although real interest may be exogenous, nominal dates are effected by inflation expections. The exogeneity of inflation expectations is a contradition in a "rational" model. 20The use Of rational expectations has been common since the mid-1970's. Some Of the earlier examples include Frenkel (1976b), Mussa (1976) and Dornbush (1976). lef PPP or equilibrium PPP were not continuous, the IRP and Fisher equation interpretations would not be equivalent. 22In some solutions, past, as well as current and future values describe the exchange rate path. 23Girton and Roper (1976) did the initial study. 24The models Of Kouri (1976) and Calvo and Rodriguez (1977) are examples Of this formulation. 2SCurrency substitution models Often specify money demand as a function Of wealth. 26This parameter is dependent upon the interest elasticity Of money demand. 27The term "commodity" should be considered synonymous with "output." 28No good dynamic models are discussed in the terms-Of-trade section. 29 The analysis presented parallels a one good Dornbush (1976) model or Frankels' (1979) model without “secular" inflation. 30The relationship between overshooting and the price adjustment mechanism is discussed in Either (1979), Mussa (1982) and others. 31See, for example, Mussa (1981). 32A model Of continuous equilibrium which allows deviations from PPP is developed by Stockman (1980). 33See Dornbush (1976), Mussa (1982) and references therein. 34See Kouri (1976), Dornbush and Fisher (1980), Rodriguez (1980). 35The portfolio balance model determines the relative level Of spot and expected future exchange rates. The determination Of absolute levels require a general specification which includes prices. Consequently, the portfolio balance effect can be integrated into the earlier models. 37 36A formal derivation Of risk is presented by Solnik (1974) and Dornbush (1980). An empirical application is found in Isard (1980). 37See Kreinin and Officer (1978) for earlier references. CHAPTER III SOME POPULAR MODELS OF EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION 3.1 - Introduction The develOpment Of the monetary/asset approach to exchange rate determination was reviewed in Chapter II. Although each model defined exchange rate equilibrium in terms Of asset stocks, disparate and sometimes contradictory specifications were produced. This chapter develops and estimates five Of the most popular models. The models represent three distinct views Of exchange rate determination within the monetary/asset approach. The "pure“ monetary or continuous equilibrium models Of Bilson (1978) and Frenkel (1976) are representative Of the "Chicago" school.1 The Dornbush (1976) and Frankel (1979) specifications are disequilibrium monetary models.2 Finally, the Hooper and Morton (1980) model includes both real 3 and portfolio balance considerations.4 exchange rate effects The exposition Of the models is twofold. First, the models are develOped directly from the behavioral assumptions and adjustment mechanisms suggested by the author. Second, the models are developed within the Isard identity. This allows for the comparison Of the models within a common framework. Section 3.2 introduces the the accounting framework develOped by Isard (1982) which equates the exchange rate with price differentials, interest rate chferentials, expected inflation differentials, risk, 38 39 and the expected real exchange rate. Section 3.3 develops the models Of Bilson (1978), Frenkel (1976), Dornbush (1976), Frankel (1979), and Hooper and Morton (1982). Section 3.3 is intended to introduce models Of greater and greater generality within the asset approach. Section 3.4 presents estimable forms of the models and discusses estimation procedures. Section 3.5 presents and interprets the results Of the estimation. Section 3.6 Offers a summary and conclusions as to which hypothesis is supported by the results. Two appendices are also included. The first discusses modeling Of unobservable variables. The second cites data sources. 3.2 - Isard's Formulation An accounting framework develOped by Isard (1982) is a useful tOOl for develOping behavioral models Of exchange rate determination. The framework includes monetary, real and portfolio balance effects. The interest rate parity condition coupled with definitions of risk and the real exchange rate provide a foundation for analysis. (1) f = s + r - r* Interest Rate Parity Condition (2) Etrisk = Ets - f Risk Identity (3) q = s + p* - p Real Exchange Rate Identity (3') th = Ets + Etp* - Etp Expected Real EXchange Rate Identity where s, f are the logs Of the spot and forward exchange rates defined as the price Of foreign currency risk is the risk premium p, p* are the logs Of the domestic and foreign price levels r, r* are domestic and foreign interest rates q is the lgg_of the real exchange rate E is the expectations Operator 40 Combining (1) (2) and - (3') yields: (4) S = Etp - Etp* + r* - r + th - Etrisk The framework is completed in two steps. First, expected logarithmic price levels are approximated by: (5) EtP = P + W and (5') Etp* = p* + n* where it and 1r* are domestic and foreign expected inflation rates. Second, equations (5) and (5') are substituted into equation (4): (6) s = (p - p*) - (r - r*) + (ii- r*) + th - Etrisk The exchange rate reflects relative prices, relative interest rates, relative expected inflation rates, the expected real exchange rate and expected risk. Note that equation (6) is an accounting identity and not an equilibrium condition. The addition Of behavioral assumptions are needed to generate a fully specified model. 3.3 Some Popular Exchange Rate Models Competing explanations Of exchange rate determination exist within the monetary/asset approach. This section examines five popular models and identifies their similarities and differences. The explication is twofold. First, the models are developed from their behavioral assumptions, market specifications and adjustment mechanisms. Second, the models are examined within a cannon frame- work, the Isard identity. The conceptual perspective forms the foundation for later empirical analysis. 41 The models develOped and estimated by Bilson (1978) and Frenkel (1976) are early variants Of the monetary/asset approach. These pure monetary specifications are representative Of the "Chicago" school. According to this view, the exchange rate is assumed tO reflect the ratio Of price levels between countries. Flexible prices ensure that purchasing power parity (PPP) and, consequently, exchange rate equilibrium hold continuously. A further assumption, price levels determined solely in the money markets, accounts for the pure monetary nature of the models. The Bilson and Frenkel models are formally derived by substi- tuting money market specifications into the equilibrium exchange rate equations. Assuming the equilibrium exchange rate is defined by PPP gives: (7) s = p - 6* where “-" denotes equilibrium value. Bilson models price levels using conventional money demand equations with identical parameters for both countries: (8) m - P = oy - 1r (9) m* - p* = ¢y* - 1r* where m, m* are lgg§_of domestic and foreign money supplies y, y* are logs Of domestic and foreign real outputs. Frenkel adapts an alternative specification: (10) m - p = 6y - An and (11) m* - p* = ¢y* - xn* 42 The assumption Of continuous PPP eliminates the distinction between current and equilibrium values. Substituting equations (8) and (9) into (7) yields the Bilson model: (12) s = (m-m*) - ¢(y-y*) + §(r-r*) Substituting equation (10) and (11) into (7) gives the Frenkel speci- fication: (13) s = (In-m) - ¢(y-y*) + Mir-r*) Coefficient signs Of the independent variables reflect the monetary nature of exchange rate determination. Increases in the domestic money supply will depreciate the spot rate by raising domestic prices. Increases in domestic-income increase demand for money and appreciate the spot rate. Finally, increases in the domestic interest rate or expected inflation rate decrease the demand for domestic money and depreciate the currency. The similarity Of the Bilson and Frenkel specifications stem from the assumption Of continuous PPP. An examination Of the models within the Isard framework (equation 6) reveals three common restrictions. First, the nominal interest. rate differential equals the) expected inflation differential. This implies real interest rates are equal across countries. Second, the log Of the real exchange rate is zero. Restated, the law Of one price holds in conmodity markets. Third, expected risk is zero. Consequently, assets are perfect substitutes. These common restrictions imply theoretical equivalence between the models. In contrast to the monetary models of the "Chicago" school, Dornbush (1976) explicitly allows for short run deviations from equilibrium PPP. This result stems from a dichotomy in market 43 adjustment mechanisms. Dornbush assumes prices adjust slowly in commodity markets while asset prices adjust instantaneously. Consequently, the spot exchange rate can deviate from its equilibrium value in the short run. Three assumptions in addition to the previously specified money market and equilibrium exchange rate equations form the model. First, uncovered interest rate parity holds continuously: the forward premium or expected rate Of depreciation, d, equals the nominal interest rate differential. (14) d = r - r* Second, the expected rate Of depreciation is a function Of the difference between the equilibrium and spot exchange rate: (15) d = 9 (§ - s) where 9 is a speed Of adjustment coefficients. Third, the expected inflation differential is zero when the exchange market is in equilibrium. The solution Of the model is straightforward. Combining equations (14) and (15) yields (16) r — r* = O(§-s) The disequilibrium nature Of the model is revealed in this equation. It is evident that the spot rate deviates from equilibrium directly with interest rate differentials. Substituting equation (13) for 5, setting (nhn*)=0 and rearranging terms gives6 (17) s = (m-m*) - 6(y-y*) - B(r-r*) The Dornbush model suggests an alternative explanation for exchange rate movements. While the signs Of the money supply and income terms parallel the monetary models Of Frenkel and Bilson, the interest rate differential has an Opposite effect on the spot rate. 44 This result is directly attributable to deviations from PPP allowed by equation (16). The existence Of "sticky" prices alters the interpre- tation Of interest rate movements. Consider for example a decrease in the domestic money supply without a proportional decrease in domestic prices. Domestic interest rates rise to clear the money market. The interest rate differential creates an inflow Of foreign capital and, consequently, an apprecia- tion Of the exchange rate. Equilibrium is restored in the exchange market as prices fall.7 Interpretation Of interest rate movements reflect the equilibrium/disequilibrium nature Of underlying price changes. In the Bilson-Frenkel type models, interest rate changes are associated with changes in inflation expectations. Higher expected price levels, indicated by increasing interest rates, depreciate the spot rate. In the Dornbush model, higher interest rates reflect tighter money market conditions caused by slowly adjusting prices in the goods market. A real interest rate differential, indicated by a nominal differential, creates a capital inflow and spot appreciation. The relationship between the equilibrium and disequilibrium models is further clarified by the use Of Isard's identity. The Dornbush model follows from equation (6) by assuming 1) the expected inflation differential is zero; 2) the real exchange rate is constant; 3) no risk premium exists; and, 4) the equilibrium exchange rate is defined by PPP. Either specification Of the price level yields equation (17), the Dornbush specification. The real interest rate differential implicit in Dornbush is modelled explicitly by Frankel (1979). Both expected inflation rates 45 and nominal interest rates are included in the exchange rate adjust- ment condition. (18) r - r* = e(§-s) + n-n* This formulation allows for changes in the nominal interest. rate differential without concurrent exchange market disequilibrium. Further, deviations from equilibrium are synonymous with [gal_interest rate differentials. The Frankel model is completed by substituting equation (9) for E in equation (18) and solving for s: (19) s = (m-m*) - 6(y-y*) - %(r-r*) + (%+X)(n—n*) Equation (19) follows directly from Isard's identity, equation (6), if we assume 1) the real exchange rate is constant; 2) no risk premium; and, 3) long run PPP with prices modeled by either conven- tional or Cagen-type money demand functions. This model extends the monetary/asset approach by differentiating the roles Of interest rates and expected inflation rates on exchange rate movements. Thus far, deviations from PPP are considered disequilibrium phenomena. This result is a consequence Of two assumptions: the law Of one price in the asset markets and a constant real exchange rate. The former assumption eliminates exchange rate movements associated with imperfect asset substitution. The latter removes effects associated with changes in the real economy. The Hooper and Morton (1980) model relaxes both restrictions. Eliminating‘ the assumption Of perfect substitution, between domestic and fOreign assets introduces exchange risk. Consequently, the IRP condition (equation (14)) no longer reflects asset market equilibrium. A risk premium, in addition to the interest rate differential, is needed to clear the market. 46 (20) d = r-r* + Etrisk Combining equations (20) and (18) yields (21) s = ‘s' - %[(r-r*) + n-ir* — Etrisk] The existence Of risk creates disequilibrium in the exchange market if real interest rates are equalized. A general version Of the monetary/asset model is completed by allowing changes in the real exchange rate. The real economy can now effect the nominal exchange rate directly. Further, real exchange rate movements cause equilibrium deviations from PPP. (22) 6 = § + 5* - 5 Combining equations (7), (8) and (22) yields a solution for s. Substituting this result into equation (21) completes the model. (23) s = (m-m*) - ¢(y-y*) - %(r-r*) + (%+1)(n-w*) + th - % Etrisk This result also follows directly from equation (6), Isard's identity, when assuming the price component is modeled by conventional money demand equations. 3.4 - Estimation Rather than estimating each specification individually, a general model will be estimated which includes each Of the previous specifi- cations as restricted cases. This will allow comparisons between models in a unified framework. Tests conducted upon alternative restrictions will be used to evaluate the empirical viability Of the competing models.8 The general model is an unrestricted version Of the Hooper and Morton specification: (26) s a1+u2m-a3m*-a4y+osy*-a6r +97"*+93 ~°9*+91oq+9urisk 47 All of the models presented in Section 3.3 carry two common restrictions: l) 012 = 013 = 1 and ii) a4 = OS The assumption Of unitary elasticity Of prices with respect to money embodied in standard money demand equations accounts for the first restriction. The assumption that domestic and foreign money demand equations have identical coefficients accounts for the second. The alternative models can now be defined by additional restrictions: 1. Bilson: ' 0.6 = 417 Mid a8 = 39 = 0.10 3 all = 0 2. Frenkel: a8 = (19 and as = 017 = “10 = 0‘11 = 0 Frankel 1: a6 = a7, a8 = 019 and 0110 =0111 = 0 01-9 Frankel 2: 016 = O7, 018 = 019 and 0:10 = O 6. HOOper and Morton: 016 = 01-, and 018 = 0:9 It should be noted that the interest rate restriction imposed in the Bilson model reflects the assumption Of identical domestic and foreign money demand equation. However, the interest rate restriction in the Dornbush, Frankel 1, Frankel 2, and HOOper and Morton models follow from assumptions concerning price adjustment rather than money demand considerations. Equation (26) will be estimated in unrestricted form and with money supply coefficients set equal to one. Frankel correctly notes that this does not impose the restriction of equal money demand 48 elasticities if we believe in the homogeneity of money with respect tO the exchange rate a_prigri. The general model will be estimated using the U.S. dollar-mark and U.S. dollar-Canadian dollar exchange rates. The U.S. dollar-mark rate was chosen for several reasons. The unexpected volatility Of the U.S. dollar-mark calls particular attention tO this rate. The large intra- and intercountry variations in money growth rates, interest rates, inflation rates, and real growth rates throughout the post-Bretton Woods period suggest this rate is particularly well suited for both the equilibrium and disequilibrium models. Further, the pOpularity Of this exchange rate as expressed in previous empirical studies allows for comparisons of results. It should be noted that the Germany participates in a joint float with other European countries. Consequently, the exchange value of the mark does not float "cleanly" against the dollar. However, the mark dominates the other currencies as an international money. Due to this fact, the D.M. participation in the snake has minimal effects on the dollar-mark exchange rate.9 The Canadian rate is Of special interest for two reasons. First, the large volume Of trade flows should shed particular light on real exchange rate effects. Second, the relative similarity Of inflation expectations during certain periods will test Frankel's contention that model performance is related tO variations in expected inflation differentials. The sample period consists Of monthly Observations between April, 1973 and March, 1983. The structural stability Of the coefficients 49 are examined by estimation Of the five-year periods preceding and following March 1978.10 The model is estimated by ordinary least squares and instrumental variables with interest rates, inflation expectations, the expected real exchange rate, and expected risk considered endogenous. Following Frankel (1981), ratios Of outstanding government debt to monetary base and long term interest rates are used as instruments for short term interest rates and expected inflation rates, respectively. Instruments for the expected real exchange rate and expected risk include cumulative current. account balances and government. budget deficits. Lagged values Of all endogenous and included exogenous variables are also included as instruments to remove serial correla- tion. Complete structural models are estimated in the next chapter. 3.5 - Results: Summary Of Estimation Comparison Of the different theoretical specifications is based upon four criteria: tests Of 1) coefficient equality restrictions; 2) coefficient sign, 3) coefficient significance; and, 4) coefficient stability. These criteria are examined for the sample period and two subperiods. Further, they are examined for three different inflation expectations proxies: adaptive, rational, and survey. Germany and Canada are analyzed separately before a general conclusion is drawn. The results are based upon ordinary least squares and two-stage least squares estimation corrected for serial correlation. All unrestricted and restricted versions Of the general model were autocorrelated over the sample and subsamples examined. One explanation for the existence Of autocorrelation in monthly Observations is government intervention in the exchange market, an 50 omitted variable in the general model.11 Evidence suggests that over a quarterly period serial correlation is not present. A. Germany. Tests Of equality restrictions imposed by assuming identical money demand functions generally failed for money supplies, interest rates, and inflation rates but held for income. This suggests that restricted versions Of the general model which do not have theoretical origins will lead tO biased estimates. Thus, both the Bilson and Frenkel models must be analyzed using either the general model or a restricted model with the coefficient on the difference between the l_09_ Of the money supplies set to one. The Dornbush, Frankel, and HOOper and Morton models must have inflation rates unrestricted. Further, if the speed Of adjustment term is separated into domestic and foreign components, then the interest rates must be unrestricted.12 The preceding analysis implies four specifications: the general model and three restricted versions. All restrictions are a_prigri assumptions imposed by theoretical relationships posited in the earlier exchange rate models. Therefore, the tables tO follow report the four specifications: (27) e = “1c + azm + a3m* + a4y + a5y* + o6r + a7r‘k + a8"- + agn" + aloq + allRTSk (28) e - m + m* = alc + o4y + a5y* + a6r + o7r* + can + o9n* + aloq + allRisk (29) e = alc + o12(m - m*) + a4y + o5y* + a13(r - r*) + can + agn* + aloq + allRisk 51 (30) e - m + m* = “1° + day + a5y* = a13(r - r*) + C18“ + agTI* + (1qu + allRi 5k Equation (27) is the general model. Equation (28) sets the coeffi- cients Of domestic and foreign money supplies to one and negative one, respectively; Equation (29) restricts the money supply coefficients and interest rate coefficients to be equal across countries. Equation (30) sets the money supply coefficient equal to one. Tables 3.1, 3.2, and 3.3 report OLS and IV estimates Of the four preceding specifi- cations for the sample period and two subperiods. Ordinary least squares and instrumental variable (IV) estimates Of the general model over the sample period yield domestic and foreign money supply coefficients of the wrong sign. The first subsample from January 1974 tO March 1978, yielded correct signs. They were, however, significantly different from the hypothesized values Of one and negative one. The second subsample estimates, from April, 1978 to March, 1983, were Of the wrong sign. Constraining the money supply coefficients tO equal and Opposite signs did not alter the results: the coefficient was generally Of the wrong sign and always signi- ficantly different than one. Estimates Of the domestic and foreign income term were generally Of the expected sign and were significant in six out Of eight cases using instrumental variables estimation. Both subsamples.,yielded similar results with coefficients found highly significant using ordinary least squares estimation over the first subsample. 'The fhndings pertaining to domestic and foreign interest rates are particularly important: The expected sign Of interest rates distinguishes between the alternative theories. It was found that 52 TABLE 3.1 REGRESSIONS OF THE GENERAL AND RESTRICTED MODELS ON THE LOG OF MARK-U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE ’T— 1974:1 - 1983:3 Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) c 5.99 4.83 1.95 -.145 7.55 6.92 2.80 3.90 (1.05) (0.96) (1.30) (1.62) (1.71) (1.32) (1.10) (1.60) m—m* 1.00 t -0.48 1.00 1.00 -0.06 1.00 (cstr) (0.28) (cstr) (cstr) (0.34) (cstr) m -o.79‘ -0.94 (0.31) (0.92) m* 0.18 0.20 (0.23) (0.61) y -0.59b -0.33 -0.20 0.05 -1.23b -1.27b -l.56b -2.08b (0.22) (0.25) (0.25) (0.24) ((0.37) (0.46) (0.47) (0.70) y* 0.10 -0.30 -0.03 0.48 0.51 0.20 1.18b 1.55b (0.19) (0.21) (0.27) (0.32) (0.33) (0.37) (0 32) (0.47) r-r* -2.96b -2.20‘ 2.90 5.23 (1.11) (1.08) (2.14) (3.05) r 2.65 8.79d 4.36 14.06d (2.08) (1.97) (4.87) (3.07) r* 3.41b 3.25b 2.14 1.87 (1.02) (1.14) (1.77) (2.12) n 7.12 18.96b 6.72 1.63 1.39 3.31 1.72b 3.11b (4.14) (4.18) (4.96) (5.23) (1.98) (1.97) (0.47) (0.24) 'n*‘} -15.30b -19.81° -8.52b -4.15 -3.94b -s.14b -o.98b -1.21b _,/ (1.40) (1.27) 2.34) (3.13) (0.67) (0.34) (0.11) (0.13) q 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.05 0.12 -0.13 (0.01) (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.10) (0.09) (0.11) (0.14) Risk -1.92a 2.31d 1.16 -O.87 —2.83 2.38d 1.14c 1.23d (0.98) (0.38) (0.75) (1.41) (2.47) (0.41) (0.37) (0.56) 42 0.85 0.86 0.27 0.09 0.v. 1.99 1.99 2.20 2.24 1.99 1.97 2.00 1.98 8 0.04 0.42 0.08 0.96 0.28 0.32 0.27 0.34 Standard errors are in parentheses. Equations (1) - (4) estimated using Cochrane-Orcutt procedure. Equations (5) - (8) estimated using Ray Fair's procedure to correct for serial correlation Of instrumental variable estimates. significant at .05 level, correct sign significant at .01 level, correct sign significant at .05 level, incorrect sign significant at .01 level, incorrect sign constrained ”GOOD IIIII 523 TABLE 3.2 REGRESSIONS OF THE GENERAL AND RESTRICTED MODELS ON THE L9§_OF MARK-U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE 1974:1 - 1978:3 Variable (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) c 11.88 0.74 0.67 0.41 5.77 0.89 0.67 0.76 (1.74) (1.64) (1.53) (1.56) (5.16) (2.31) (2.65) (2.64) m-m* 1.00 t 0.38 1.00 1.00 1.27 1.00 (cstr) (0.38) (cstr) (cstr) (1.05) (cstr) m 0.55 0.74 (0.37) (0.77) m* -2.86b -1.85 (0.57) (1.08) y -O.80b —O.82b -0.88b -O.83b -0.47 0.08 -o.71 -0.74 (0.29) (0.30) (0.29) (0.30) (0.80) (0.88) (1.04) (1.05) y* 1.30b 0.88b 0.89b 0.96b 0.76 -0.19 1.01 0.99 (0.31) (0.35) (0.29) (0.30) (0.87) (0.63) (0.63) (0.62) r-r* -1.53 -O.91 3.14 2.62 (1.80) (1.79) (4.32) (4.06) r -1.02 -O.36 5.65 14.04c (2.54) (2.78) (6.70) (6.00) r* -1.72 1.48 -0.95 2.54 (2.30) (2.55) (4.94) (3.97) n -3.78 1.92 -0.40 0.94 3.78 8.20b 1.50a 1.50a (5.41) (6.18) (5.80) (5.82) (3.92) (2.26) (0.68) (0 61) .u4 -1.16 -2.40 -2.41 -2.16 -1.16 -2.13’ -0.33 -0.41 (2.90) (3.49) (3.17) (3.21) (1.18) (1.09) (0.31) (0.28) q 0.08 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.22 0.28 0.04a 0.04a (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.16) (0.15) (0.01) (0.02) Risk -1.78 -0.36 -O.56 -0.30 -1.67 -3.17 3.70 3.12 (1.35) (1.39) (1.41) (1.32) (2.53) (3.01) (2.88) (2.17) R2 0.81 0.26 0.29 0.27 0.v. 1.79 1.88 1.87 1.90 1.77 1.85 1.79 1.80 a 0.42 0.96 0.96 0.97 0.24 0.22 0.25 0.29 Standard errors in parentheses. Equations (1) - (4) estimated using Cochrane-Orcutt procedure. Equations (5) - (8) estimated using Ray Fair's procedure to correct for serial correlation "GOOD Of instrumental variable estimates. significant at significant at significant at significant at constrained .05 level, correct sign .01 level, correct sign .05 level, incorrect sign .01 level, incorrect sign 54' TABLE 3.3 REGRESSIONS OF THE GENERAL AND RESTRICTED MODELS ON THE LOG OF MARK-U.S. DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE 1978z4 - 1983:3 Variable (I) (2) (3) (4) (5) (5) (7) (8) c 0.62 0.75 -2.07 -2.65 2.50 3.25 -2.00 -o.83 (2.61) (2.14) (1.90) (2.32) (4.12) (0.83) (3.16) (3.25) m—m* 1.00 -0.70 1.00 1.00 -0.52 1.00 (0.35) (0.76) m -o.21 -0.99 (0.46) (1.36) m* 0.28 0.40 (0.37) (1.07) y -0.11 0.05 -0.19 -0.13 -0.35 -0.56 -0.62 -1.05 (0 28) (0.30) (0.29) (0.34) (0.55) (0.57) (0.61) (0.69) y* 0.21 -0.15 0.51 0.41 0.60 0.26 1.29” 1.45” (0.37) (0.37) (0.33) (0.41) (0.64) (0.58) (0.44) (0 42) r-r* -3.46” -3.39‘ 2.71 3.30 (1.14) (1.37) (2.42) (2 54) r 2.88 7.27“ 5.00 13.58“ (2.94) (2.82) (7.24) (5.11) r* 3.80” 3.84” -.25 -0.52 (1.13) (1.20) (2.62) (2.58) n -3.40 1.98 2.83 18.17” 2.62 4.34 1.698 2.31” (6.08) (7.23) (6.57) (6.88) (3.78) (3.68) (0.82) (0.67) n* -12.39” -19.58” -11.15” -20.70” -4.48” -5.74” -1.08” -1.49” (3.05) (2.21) (2.93) (2.61) (1 39) (0.82) (o 34) (0 21) q -0.01 0.01 -0.01 -0.02 0.11 0.11 0.06 0.08 (0.03) (0.04) (0.03) (0.04) (0.09) (0.10) (0.12) (0.13) Risk -3.79° -4.82” -4.30‘ -6.63b -0.77 2.12 2.94 -1.31 (1.82) (1.87) (1.81) (2.10) (4.32) (2.97) (3.46) (3.04) R2 0.79 0.87 0.78 0.80 0.v. 1.86 1.90 1.95 2.07 1.88 1.93 2.00 2.00 6 .60 .57 .58 .61 .44 .35 .39 .26 Standard errors Equations (1) - Equations (5) - (8) estimated using Ray Fair's procedure to correct for serial correlation an U9 in parentheses. (4) estimated using Cochrane-Orcutt procedure. of instrumental variable estimates. significant at .05 level, correct sign significant at .01 level, correct sign significant at .05 level, incorrect sign significant at .01 level, incorrect sign 55 both domestic and foreign interest rates were positively correlated with the exchange rate using both OLS and IV techniques. This result did not change when the log difference Of money supplies was set to one, a theoretical restriction present in all exchange rate determination theories examined. The results also show that fully half Of the estimates were significant at the one percent level. Estimates Obtained from the earlier subsample carry negative signs in OLS estimation and positive correlations using IV techniques. In either case, the coefficients are insignificant in seven Of eight cases. The later subsample has results similar to the sample as a whole. The estimates obtained when restricting interest rate coeffi- cients to equal and Opposite signs diverge radically from unrestricted estimates. Ordinary least squares results find the correlation negative and significant although both interest rate coefficients were positive in the unrestricted model. (This result can be explained by the statistical properties of the restriction. See Haynes and Stone (1981)). The instrumental variable estimates had positive and insignificant coefficients on the interest rate differential. These results are also found in the earlier subsample. While the second subsample carried the same signs, the estimates were insignificant. It should also be noted that the correlation coefficient of both the sample and earlier subsample drOp dramatically when the interest rate differential is substituted for interest rate levels. Estimates Of inflation expectations, when proxied by an adaptive model, were found significant at the one percent level in ten Of sixteen cases and were always of the expected sign13. Estimates Of 56 the April, 1978 to March, 1983 period mirrored these results with eleven Of sixteen cases significant. Results from the earlier subperiod were insignificant using OLS but improved using IV: four Of eight coefficients were significant and all Of the expected sign. When IBIIQEIQO-§XQ§Ctat10nS were proxied using an interpolated OECD survey, the estimates were generally Of the expected sign but insignificant. The results Of the second subperiod are superior to the first. There are, however, two reasons to discount these results. First, the expectations have an eighteen-month horizon, a length generally acknowledged to be shorter than the "long run.“ Second, the survey is based partially on Opinion research and partially upon the OECD model. Improvements in the model can possibly account for the surveys' increased success in the second subperiod. BisignanO and Hoover (1980) have found that the Livingston survey yields positive and significant estimates. However, it also suffers from the first criticism. Attempts to estimate the model when inflation expectations were derived rationally failed to produce significant estimates and, in the case Of United States inflation rates, failed to produce the correct sign. The estimation procedure, suggested by McCallum (1976).Usedwm QQPHQLIVIUIE,__.I-DII9W)" rates while including the variables Of, them information set in thefllist Of instrumental variables. The time..- horizon‘was chosen from estimates found in the literature and, this,” -limited estimation to the first subsample. Estimates of the real exchange rate generally carried the correct sign but failed the significance tests. The most encouraging results were found during the earlier subperiod. \/ 57 ' The risk variable showed mixed results for the entire sample period but significant results for the second subperiod. Previous evidence suggests the risk premium is time varying. The results conform tO that conclusion. Since the demand component Of the risk term is included in the coefficient the results also conform to an alternative hypothesis: the habitat of OPEC investments has changed since the second Oil shock.14 The structural stability of the general model is called into question by comparison Of coefficient estimates Of the two subperiods. Examination Of the general model coefficients show that money supplies, interest rates, foreign inflation rates, and real exchange rates produce significantly different OLS and IV estimates. This result is confirmed using estimates Obtained in the exchange rate literature: the general model is sensitive to choice Of sample period, especially with respect tO money supplies, interest rates and risk. 8. Canada. The Canadian regressions reported in Tables 3.4, 3.5, and 3.6 show domestic money supply coefficients Of the correct sign and foreign coefficients of the incorrect sign. _ In general, both coefficients differ significantly from one. The restricted money supply estimates are also Of the expected sign and insignificant with the exception Of IV estimates covering the whole sample period. However, it is significantly different from one, the theoretical expectation. The income terms carry the expected sign in nineteen Of twenty-four cases and over half Of the coefficients are significant. The results are especially strong using IV techniques in the entire sample—period, and second subsample. The incorrect signs are Regressions Of the General and Restricted Models 523 Table 3-4 on the ng_of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate l974:l - 1983:3 variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) c -l.88 1.65 -O.46 0.86 -2.38 -1.09 1.09 .47 (0.63) (0.98) (0.78) (0.89) (1.71) (0.97) (0.92) (0.98) m - m* 1.00 0.02 1.00 1.00 0.58” 1.00 (0.11) (0.15) m 0.08 0.19 (0.10) (0.19) m* 0.26c 0.30 (0.12) (0 37) y 0.01 -0.15 0.01 -O.l8 -0.25 -0.76' -0.35 -0.41 (0.12) (0.17) (0.12) (0.18) (0.21) (0.35) (0.26) (0.27) y* 0.02 0.25 0.12 0.45. 0.30 1.35” 0.38“ 0.69” (0.14) (0.22) (0.15) (0.20) (0.20) (0.34) (O.l8) (0.25) r - r* -1.11 0.32 -4.56a 1.72 (0.75) (1.07) (2.08) (2.38) r 0.89 2.14 -2.65 -3.95 (0.96) (1.47) (1.4)) (2.43) r* 0.89 -O.38 1.17 -2.21 (0.73) (1.05) (1.22) (2.03) r -0.91 -O.69 -1.12 -0.45 0.27 0.45 0.14 -0.12 (1.38) (2 12) (1.53) (2.12) (0.68) (0.27) (0.12) (0.26) 4* 0.16 -0.03 0.18 0.12 0.09 -0.11 -0.19° -0.07 (1.17) (1.96) (l.48) (1.88) (0.46) (0.45) (0.08) (0.14) q -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 0.01 -0.05 0.01 (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) Risk -0.51 -2.57“ -0.53 -2.82 2.49 -7.23” -5.74” -7.29” (0.82) (l.08) (0.80) (1.06) (3.64) (1.63) (1.29) (1.80) R2 .48 .11 .50 .06 0.v. 2.36 2.21 2.60 2.23 2.10 2.02 1.99 2.18 o .83 .92 .97 .90 .56 .62 .52 .80 Equations (1) - Equations (5) - of instrumental a - significant b - significant c - significant d - significant (4) estimated using Cochrane-Orcutt procedure. (8) estimated using Ray Fair's procedure to correct for serial correlation variable estimates. at .05 level, correct sign at .Ol level, correct sign at .05 level, incorrect sign at .Ol level, incorrect sign Regression Of the General and Restricted Models 59 Table 3-5 on the ng_of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate 1974:1 - 1978:3 Variable (I) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) c -2.63 3.25 0.06 2.75 -1.12 4.18 0.35 4.36 (0.86) (1.49) (0.89) (1.33) (1.60) (2.16) (1.29) (1.76) m - m* 1.00 0.07 1.00 1.00 0.04 1.00 (0.15) (0.22) m 0.12 0.16 (0.14) (0.28) m* 0.58c 0.27 (0.24) (0.44) y -0.31 -0.23 -0.14 -0.21 -0.31 -0.34 -0.17 -0.41 (0.18) (0.29) (0.17) (0.28) (0.28) (0.36) (0.22) (0.37) y* 0.07 0.06 0.10 0.13 0.17 -0.02 ' 0.13 0.04 (0.15) (0.29) (0.16) (0.26) (0.23) (0.42) (0.18) (0.33) r - r* -0.38 -l.46 0.20 4.25 (1.40) (2.37) (2.87) (5.29) r -2.58 -O.36 -9.13” 3.75 (1.62) (2.90) (2.41) (6.39) r* 1.75 1.89 5.79a -2.22 (1.39) (2.51) (2.39) (5.06) . 2.08 -3.35 -0 49 -3.18 0.18 -1.31 0.18 -0.26 (1.59) (3.19) 1.87) (3.16) (0.71) (1.35) (0.22) (0.34) 4* 1.90 4.74 -0.02 4.48 0.11 , 1.22 -0.23 0.28 (2.21) (3.82) (2.32) (3.80) (0.89) (1.58) (0.27) (0.39) q -0.01 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.01 -0.04 -0.02 -0.03 (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) Risk -0.46 -O.38 -0.91 -0.41 1.74 2.53 -0.37 -l.87 (1 00) (1.50) (0.89) (1.49) (2.35) (2.51) (1.55) (2.57) R2 .81 .07 .07 .06 0.v. 1.89 1.93 1.89 1.96 1.70 1.64 1.90 1.91 o .50 .98 0.98 0.97 .36 .97 .92 0.95 Equations (1) - (4 Equations (5) - (8 estimated using Cochrane-Orcutt procedure. estimated using Ray Fair's procedure to correct for serial correlation Of instrumental variable estimates. a - significant at .05 level, correct Sign O - significant at .01 level, correct sign c - significant at .05 level. incorrect sign 0 - significant at .01 level, incorrect sign Regressions Of the General and Restricted Models 60 Table 3-6 on the egg of Canadian Dollar/U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate 1978:4 - 1983:3 Variable (I) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) c -O.62 0.75 -0.39 1.41 0.93 2.63 0.18 2.05 (2.62) (2.14) (0.87) (1.03) (1.82) (1.65) (1.17) (1.09) m - m* 1.00 0.03 1.00 ' 1.00 0.37 1.00 (0.17) (0.27) m -o.21 0.36 (0.46) (0.21) m* 0.28 -0.23 (0.39) (0.37) y -0.11 0.05 -0.11 -0.39 -0.29 -0.87b -O.48 -0.93” (0.28) (0.30) (0.18) (0.23) (0.20) (0.33) (0.26) (0.31) y* 0.12 -0.15 0.19 0.58' -o.1s 0.84 0.601' 1.01” (0.36) (0.37) (0.22) (0.30) (0.28) (0.48) (0.26) (0.35) r - r* -0.67 1.55 1.28 2.38 (1.00) (1.25) (1.57) (1.81) r 2.88 7.27“ 3.44“ 3.67 (2.94) (2.82) (1.58) (2.58) r* 3.80” 3.84” -1.05 -2.78 (1.13) (1.21) (1.08) (1.59) n -3.40 1.98 -o.97 -2.69 -0.70 -1.04 0.05 -0.18 (6.89) (7.23) (1.20) (1.71) (0.43) (0.82) (0.08) (0.12) 4* -12.39” -19.58” -1.99“ -O.86 -0.30 0.28 -0.143 0.06 (3 05) (2.21) (0.82) (1.09) (0.42) . (0.30) (0.06) (0.08) q -0.01 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.03 -0.02 -0.04 (0.03) (0.04) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.04) Risk -3.79a -4.83” -3.07‘ -1.91 -1.22 1.04 -4.58” 0.43 (1.82) (1.87) (1.09) (1.31) (3.74) (1.93) (1.35) (1.62) R2 .79 .87 .45 .11 0.9. 1.86 1.90 1.96 1.98 1.99 2.00 1.97 2.00 o .60 .57 .34 .46 .11 .30 .19 .30 Equations (l) - Equations (5) - of instrumental 8 - significant b - significant c - significant 0 - significant (4) estimated using Cochranc-Orcutt procedure. (8) estimated using Ray Fair‘s procedure to correct for serial correlation variable estimates. .05 level, correct sign .Ol level, correct sign .05 level, incorrect sign .0) level, incorrect sign at at at at 61 associated with regressions in which the l_O_g_ difference Of money supplies is constrained to equal one. Estimates Of domestic and foreign interest rates vary substan- tially between samples. Results from the first subperiod show the expected signs and are significant using IV on the general model. The second subsample shows mixed results: OLS estimates are positive for both domestic and foreign rates while IV estimates have incorrect signs. The sample estimates are insignificant with four Of eight signs correct. Restricting the interest rate coefficients to equal and Opposite signs does not improve the results. The sign is wrong in seven of twelve cases and significant in only one. Further, sign reversals occur in four estimates suggesting the statistical prOperties Of the restricted estimation produce spurious correlations. In seven Of the twelve cases the restricted estimate does not fall within the range Of unrestricted estimates. ‘ Estimates of inflation expectations (adaptive process) indicate that during the second subperiod foreign inflation rates contribute to the explanation Of exchange rate levels. In the first subperiod and the sample as a whole, however, inflation expectations were not significant. Further, the signs were correct in only fifty percent Of the cases. The use Of either rational or survey inflation expectation proxies did not improve the results. Although the real exchange rate was not a significant determinant of nominal exchange rate determination, the risk term proved to be significant in over half of the sample and second subsample 62 regressions. The risk coefficient was found tO have the correct sign in six Of the eight earlier subsample estimates. Tests of structural stability indicate that both interest rates and the fOreign inflation rate estimates vary significantly between periods. This lends further credence to the notion that the alter- native exchange rate models Offer no general explanation of exchange rate movements . 3.6 - Conclusion: Comparison Of Alternative Exchange Rate Models The early Optimism Of monetary and asset approaches to exchange rate determination was in part based upon positive results Obtained from money supply estimates: coefficients Of the M difference'of money supplies were significant and near unity. However, the results Of this and other studies strongly contradict that finding. This might suggest the‘iejection Of the monetary/asset approach. This conclusion, however, is overdrawn. The dependent variable can be changed from the exchange rate to the exchange rate minus the difference in money supplies. on ‘theoretical grounds: the standard money demand function imposes this restriction. While the general model test§_if the money coefficient is equal to one, the restricted model assumes it. This allows for comparison Of alternative exchange rate hypothesis without rejection Of the monetary approach.15 The mark-U.S. dollar experience lends support to models which include inflation expectations as an explanatory variable. When the second Canadian dollar-U.S. dollar subperiod is also considered, support is found for Frankel's contention that inflation expectations are a key exchange rate determinant in periods Of significant inflation and intercountry inflation differentials. The absence Of 63 significant inflation expectations estimates during the first Canadian dollar-U.S. dollar subperiod lend further credence to this argument. The second. subperiod results for: both exchange rates support portfolio balance approaches as Opposed to models which do not include risk. The evidence Of a risk premium tends to add credence“ to the contention that assets denominated in different currencies are not perfect substitutes and that exchange risk is related to national debt. When the results from the earlier subperiod and general sample are also examined several interpretations are possible. The demand side Of the asset market, which is subsumed in the risk coefficient, can account for two possibilities: first, wealth transfers between agents with different asset preferences, and second, changes in the asset preferences Of agents holding the assets. 80th explanations could be related to OPEC. Weak support is found for the real exchange rate variable in the German case. ‘The Canadian estimates, however, fail to support the hypothesis. Part of the problem lies in the theoretical underpin- nings; it is unclear whether bilateral or world trade is the correct specification. Further, it is difficult to capture changes in world import and export demand in a bilateral exchange rate model. Finally, it has been suggested that wealth effects rather than real exchange_ rate ,effectsare. captured. by current. ,accoun.’c_19..84_.-t!ie.99 .§E§$L§HE§:.. As was noted earlier, the expected sign Of the interest rate differential has been hypothesized tO be positive, negative and zero by different exchange rate models. Unfortunately, the results do not indicate a clear pattern. Unrestricted and restricted interest rate estimates in the first subperiod have signs which support the general 64 or disequilibrium model when estimated by OLS. However, the IV results produce sign reversals. 17) either: case, the results are generally insignificant. Estimates from the second subperiod conform to the Bilson specification when IV techniques are used and show identical signs with significant coefficients when estimated using OLS. German results over the sample mirror these OLS finding. Restricted versions Often have coefficients outside the range Of the unrestricted estimates. During the post-Bretton WOOds period increased interest rate differentials are associated with both appreciation and depreciation Of the exchange rate. The apparent success of the disequilibrium models during the early floating rate period found in other studies is not repeated. One explanation is the use Of monthly averages Of exchange rates and interest rates in other investigations: this violates the interest rate parity condition. The introduction Of the monetary and asset models Of exchange rate determination have integrated the advances Of monetary theory into international finance. However, it is unclear which specifi- cation most adequately represents the post-Bretton Woods experience. Some have blamed the apparent inadequacy on the money demand equation upon which all Of the above specifications rely. The simplification of the theoretical models for convenience Of estimation is an alternative explanation. 65 APPENDIX 3.A VARIABLE PROXIES AND MODELING OF UNOBSERVABLE VARIABLES The interest rate parity condition, fundamental to all the models presented, imposes strong requirements on the collection Of exchange rate and interest rate data. 80th from a theoretical and empirical perspective, slight deviations from interest rate parity are arbitraged away very quickly. Thus, spot exchange rates and interest rates must be collected at the same time or constructed to conform to IRP. In general, averages will fail to meet this condition. Proxies or models Of long term expected inflation rates pose substantial difficulties. One Often-used approach proxies expected, tnflationrate differentials with long term interest rate differen- tials (bond yields). The logic behind this approach is that interest _rate differentials equal 'Aexpected inflation differentials in equilibrium. The use Of Jongwterm interest_rates is premised by the assumption that adjustment to PPP occurs before the "long-term" is reached thus assuring real interest rates are equalized. An advantage to this proxy is that changes in the rates reflect new and up-tO-date information. This lends support to the rationality Of the proxy. However, if money demand equations are not assumed identical across countries then the use Of long-term interest rates to proxy expected inflation will bias the estimates. Although long-term real interest rates are equal across countries over time, the real interest 66 / rate is not necessarily constant over time. Problems of multi- colinearity may also present themselves when both the short- and long—term interest rate are right hand side variables. An alternative for inflation expectations js expectational survey data. This avoids the error in variables encountered when using interest rates, while preserving the rationality of the series. However, the horizon must be "long run" for real rates to be equal between countries. Estimates suggest that a horizon over two years is needed. Finally, the use Of either adaptive or rational models Of inflationary expectations present a final alternative. ‘Rationalflv ‘9§pectatiQfl$“CStimation, as prOposed by McCallum (1976), useSHQQ£uel_v/l futurefinflation values while adding variables in the information set to the list Of instruments. Adaptive processes have precedent 151399 literature although the rationality Of the expectation, is now in question. ......— -.. relative real changes in both cost and demand structures between countries. Central to this analysis is the relationship between the real exchange rate and the balance of trade popularized by the traditional "flow” ,view of exchange rate determination. The real exchange rate is expected to equilibrate the balance Of trade and assure a finite bound on net foreign debt. If this were not the case, infinite wealth transfers or infinite debt accumulation would be possible with a steady state real exchange rate, an implausible result. 67 ‘v Both current account and trade balance data have been suggested as proxies for the real exchange_rate. The use Of bilateral or "world" positions has not found a general_c0ncensus. In.either_case,g distinguishing between temporary andpermanent shifts, inunderlying L9,“) determinantsisa -.difficult_ta§k_. The use of bilateralwtradefl data, however, does have certain advantages. First, it has a_long A history Of use in the flow literature which supplies the_tbe9tetiga1- foundation for real rate. Second, “it does notflinoludefluniglatergajn transfers which do_not-.refle,ctunderlying real_,_c_h_aoges_. Third, it highlights_cost changes between differentiated.manufacturednprnducts,. EEPVIWFCY,CPWP°"°"F Of United States-German and United Stateseganadian .EC?“e° The existence Of exchange risk can be traced to private investors} uncertainty about expected spot rates and risk minimization in the currency composition Of private portfolios (Dornbush, 1980). The risk premium is affected by changes in the stock Of public debt denominated in different currencies, the distribution Of financial wealth, and private investors subjective preference for assets denominated in different currencies. If, for example, outside assets denominated in the foreign currency increase, the) immediate spot depreciation must coincide with an increase in expected appreciation for investors to accept new foreign debt into their portfolios at given interest rates. The forward rate falls relative to the expected spot rate, thereby increasing risk. A similar process occurs if wealth is transferred from a country with low home currency preference tO a country with high home currency preference. Finally, preference 68 changes within either country toward the home currency yield the same result. Dornbush (1980) has formalized this relationship in a mean/variance framework in accordance with the theory Of portfolio selection. Risk can be defined as: sQ* ”'V'wi (32) RISK = 1 ‘1' WT; 1 u .TH' where u, u* are coefficients Of risk aversion that characterize home and foreign currency preferences v is the perceived variance Of-Etst+1 - tft+1 WI, W* represent global private wealth and foreigners' private » wealth, respectively 0, 0* are the total Of outside assets denominated in domestic and foreign currency, respectively By subsuming the preference and variance components into the risk coefficient during estimation, ignoring wealth effects (i.e, u=u*), and defining global wealth as the sum Of outside assets (W=O+O*) (27) can be rewritten as: (33) (Risk - 1) u . v = sQ*/(sQ* + 0) = 1/(1 + Q/sQ*) These rather stringent assumptions are more a result Of the paucity of wealth data than an algebraic simplification. 69 APPENDIX 3.8 DATA SOURCES All data is unadjusted and end Of period unless otherwise noted. EXCHANGE RATES: MONEY SUPPLIES: INCOMES: INTEREST RATES: Short term: Long term: SUPPLY OF OUTSIDE ASSETS: Defined as DM/U.S.$, Can S/U.S.$, £/U.S.$ rates. Reported monthly for the last business day Of the month. Average Of the bid/asked spread. Financial Times (London). ““""" U.S.: M1 in billions Of U.S. dollars, monthly Germany: M1 in billions Of DM, monthly Canada: M1 in billions Of Can. dollars, monthly U.S.: M1 in billions Of pound sterling, monthly As reported in O.E.C.D. Main Economic Indicators. Index of Industrial Production in each country, monthly. As reported in O.E.C.D. Main Economic Indicators. Three month Eurocurrency Rates (LIBOR). Collected monthly on the last business day Of the month. Quoted at the identical time as the exchange rate quotations above. Reported in the Financial Times (London). U.S.: Long term bond yields, monthly. Reported in the Federal Reserve Bulletin. Germany: Yields on government securities with ten years tO maturity, monthly. Duetches Bundesbank. Canada: Long term bond yields on government securities, monthly. Bank of_Canada. U.K.: Long term bond rates (ten years or more) on government securities, monthly. Bank of England. U.S.: Federal debt held by the public, monthly. Federal Reserve Bulletin. Germany: Federal Government debt, monthly. Duetches Bundesbank. PRICES: INFLATION EXPECTATIONS: CURRENT ACCOUNTS: TRADE BALANCES: BILATERAL TRADE BALANCES: 70 Canada: Federal government debt, monthly. Bank Of Canada. U.K.: Public debt, monthly. Bank of_England. Consumer Price Indexes, all times, monthly. Reported in O.E.C.0. Main Economic Indicators. Eighteen month forecasts, bi-annually. O.E.C.D. Economic Outlook. Each country in its respective currency, quarterly. O.E.C.D. Main Economic Indicators. Each country, in its respective currency, monthly. O.E.C.D. Main Economic Indicators. U.S.: In U.S. dollars, monthly. Survey Of Current Business. Germany: In DM, monthly. Duetches Bundesbank. 71 FOOTNOTES - CHAPTER 111 1See Kreinin and Officer [1978] for detailed explanation Of the monetary approach and extensive references to empirical work. 2Disequilibrium in the context Of the Frenkel and Dornbush models refer to short run deviations from equilibrium. 3Also, see Mussa [1982] for a non-PPP model including terms-Of-trade effects. 4An extensive literature exists on the existence of a risk premium. See references contained in cited papers. 5See the appendix in Frankel (1979) for the derivation. 6The development Of alternative models retains the essential features Of the original work. 7The adjustment process describes the "overshooting" case i.e. the exchange rate overshoots its equilibrium level. Conditions for the overshooting result appear in Glassner (1982). 8See Mizon [1977] for advantages to this technique. 9Germany is now a member Of the European Mogetary System. 10The apprOpriate test statistic isi¢ VBRA+VARB-2'CUVAB where A and 8 denote estimated coefficients from different sample periods. 11This might also be explained by government action in the money market: the monetary authority can adjust the money supply to trend over time once a shock has set it Off trend. 12This specification would model goods market adjustment in each country separately. 131 adopt the Frankel (1979) process: a six month moving average Of actual inflation rates. 14See appendix for characterization Of risk. 15The assumption that actual rates are equilibrium rates in the money market could also be responsible for this result. This possibility is examined in the next chapter. 72 15Given the enormous wealth transfers to OPEC countries, an increase in the risk premium is indicated if OPEC countries find third country bonds relatively less preferable than third country residents. CHAPTER IV ESTIMATION OF THE GENERAL MODEL 4.1 Introduction In Chapter III, five popular money/asset models were tested using single equation estimation techniques. However, a majority Of the exchange rate models were originally formulated as simultaneous systems. A dichotomy is created between. theory and practice when a simultaneous model is reduced to a single equation for estimation. The estimated model is not a true test Of its theoretical precussor. The misspecification results in inconsistent estimates. Consequently, this chapter reestimates the general model using-systemutechniques. Several reasons in addition to the aforementioned methodological and statistical considerations suggest the use Of simultaneous equation techniques. "first, system estimates allow for the explicit examination Of the interest rate and price specifications. Since the behavioral assumptions inherent in the interest rate equation underly exchange rate determination, it is useful tO examine them directly. Equilibrium as well as disequilibrium adjustment is defined by the price equation in monetary models. Direct tests of the price mechanism also seem warranted. .§§£98§:~system estimation is necessary to examine the rational gxpectati ons hypothesiLspec ifiodJn4hetheoret1calJensiQnLnf. the- ._ ..999F11" The overidentifying restrictions imposed by a rational 73 74 formulation can be jointly tested with the structural assumptions by means of a likelihood ratio test Of restrictedand unrestricted estimates. “finally, the system estimates allow for an examination Of model specification and variable endogeneity.- Comparison Of ordinary least squares, two-stage least squares ”and full information maximum likelihood (FIML) estimates can be conducted using Hausman-Wu tests. A simultaneous version Of the restricted model will be examined in Section 4.2. Driskill and Sheffrin (1981) have estimated the model without risk under rational expectations assuming the Frankel (1979) price adjustment mechanism and specific lag structures for the exogenous variables. Several refinements are considered. A discus- sion Of the estimation techniques and testing procedures is also included. Section 4.3 reports the results Of the estimation for the mark-U.S. dollar and Canadian dollar-U.S. dollar exchange rates over the sample period beginning January 1974 and ending March 1983. IT) Section 4.4, tests of the model are conducted over thgfllgggwmw through Iggggperiod to see whether the persistent appreciation Of the U.S. dollar is explained by any Of the alternative specifications. Claims Of the U.S. dollar's overvaluation by some Observers lend prior support to the real interest differential models. Others believe that exchange risk or the "safe haven“ argument Offers an explanation for the dollar's strength. Estimates Of the U.S. dollar-U.K. pound sterling exchange rate are included for this sample period. A sumary is Offered in Section 4.5. 75 4.2 An Econometric Model The simultaneous model presented in this section is an econo- metric specification of the single equation restricted model presented in Chapter II. The relative price level and interest rate differential are endogenous while specific processes for the exogenous variables are considered. The stochastic processes of the exogenous variables place overidentifying restrictions on the model allowing examination of the rational expectations hypothesis, a hypothesis assumed in many of the theoretical models. The covered interest arbitrage condition is assumed to hold: or (1) rt-rt* = Et St+1 - st + riskt Risk arises when assets denominated in different currencies are not considered perfect substitutes. In the absence of risk, open interest rate arbitrage exists. Traditional money demand equations are posited with coefficients on income and interest rates held equal across countries. An error term is added to the equation. (2) (m-m*)t - (p-p*)t = ¢Kyop do. an acoUmecmpm - a guru uumcgou .—m>mp mo. um acouwwwcmwm - a .mommgucotma cw «Locum ugaucaum Amo.. .Ho.. .Aoo.v Ahoo.v NM. mm.H mm. moo. ass. memo. mflo.- a uaou Huaahnpv Huakannv Him 0 Aafio.. .moc.. Ammo.. Amoo.. we. mm.H mm. mmo. ammo. -o.- “Ho.- A«L-L. ugou «Ho.v Ease.“ .moo.. Amoo.. am. he. ammo. amao. aaHo.- ¢H0.- Ate-a. moo ANN.HV .oe.v RH~.. ANm.V .m~.. Asm.v o. 0H.~ om. Hm.H- nm¢.~ m~.- cm. umm.- mm. m Qmou .mo.H. ~m~.V bem.. Am~.v .m~.. .mm.. mo.H om. om. no~.m amm.- amo. aoH.H- ON. 3 was @ .=.a Na gm“ .=-= «a-» aa-a «5-2 u aa> soaps: mummmauauenma muhzmp Ho. an acmupevcmwm . a .mommgucmcma =_ mgogto ugmucuum Ammo.v Aeo.v Ammo.v ammo.. em. Hm.fi om. hmo.- a~m. muo. mNo.- a omou H-A.=.=e H-..s-a. a-“ a .-o.. Ammo.v Am~o.v Aflo.. so. hm.H mo. HNQ. «no. mmo. Ho.- Asa-av uaou .mfio.v Acco.. Ammo.v .AHo.V mm. mH. Hmo. «do. Boo. moo.- ..t-av moo Amm.fi. AAA.. .m~.. RAH.HV Ann.. .94.. mm. 0H.~ on. mo.- on. am~.- he.” me. Ne. w umou Amm.g. A~¢.. .m~.. .Aa.. Ame.v .om.. mo.~ ms. mH.H- oNo. am~.H- nmo.~ em. oo.H m mac n .:.o Na emu .=-= as-» .a-s .s-e o aa> venom: mumsmauauenma muhzmp mo. an pcuupmwcmwm u cmpm uuoccou .Po>op Ho. an u:~u_w_:mwm . a cmwm uumccou .Pm>up mo. no acuupmpcmpm - a .mommzucocuq =_ mcoegu vcuucaum ANNO.V ANo.. Amoo.v Amoo.. NN. No.N Na. Nmo. Na. Hoo.- Noo.- .«a-av mac atgn=v Huaxauav Hum u .NNo.. Asmo.. Aoeo.. .oNo.. mm. oa.H mo. «ea. NNo. mmo.- mNo.- Asa-av NNON RNNo.. .HNo. AmNo.v .moo.. om. NN. name. «no. ammo.- .omo.- ..a-a. moo AN¢.HV “no. .mN.. AN¢.N AN¢.V ame.. mo. ON.N mo. AN. ao¢.N NN.- «N.- NN.- Nm. m umou .NN.N. .em.v .oN.. NN. .N¢.. .NN.. NN.H as. mo.N amo.m aNm.- «a. uNo.N- mN.- a mac n .:.o NN gm“ s=-= «a-» sq-a as.s N aa> vogue: mummmaucumnma mmhzmp Ho. an acou_mw=mwm . a cm_m uumgtou .Pm>op mo. an acmupwwcmwm . a .mmmmzucmeuq cw mucosa ucmucmpm .ONo.V .eNo.v Amoo.v mace. NN.N NN. aNao. aNNm. aoNo. coco. ..s-a. who H-A.e.=e N-,.a-a. a-” u .mNo.v .oeo.v aNo.v Aeo.v NN. Nam. 8o. Noo.- coo.- nmo.- No.- «L.2 NNON AeNo.v ACNo.V Amo.v ANo.. mNo. a mmo. No.- «0.- «2.2 mac RON. ANN.V NNN.. Amm.v .oN.V ”om.v NN. oo.N N0. N8. oN.- No. NN.- mo. NN. m Naou .em.. Am”. .oN.. ANN.V Aoo.v .N~.v mm. mm. mm.o No. nom.- 4N. awn. Ne. 6 mac N .=.o NN NNN 48-8 «a-» «8-8 «5-5 u LN> 88:86: NHNNNN-NH¢NNN mmemp Ho. no oooooooooom - o cm_m pumccou .Pmoop mo. an acoupoocmom . o .mmmozucocoo co mgogcm ucovcopm Aooo.. mo. Aooo.o .ooo.o oH.N oo. ooo. mo. omoo. oooo. to-o moo HINLFIFV Mafia-A: Him 0 Aooo.o Aooo.o Aooo.o oo. No.o oo. Nmo. moo. ooo. ta-a omoo AoNo.o ”Noo.. ANoo.o .oNo.o ooo. oooo. Noo.- ooo. «L-L moo .oo.. Aom.. ANNN.. .oo.o .Nmo.o Rom.o oN.N oo. NN. oN.- Hoo.- No. , NNo.- NN.- m oooo .No.mo .om.o ANoN.o ANo.o. AoNN.o Aoo.. No. NN. oo.m NN.- moo. ooN.N ooo.- No.- 8 moo o .:.o No goo .o.: to.» so-o «5.5 o too oooomz NuoNoN-NHoNoN mmoup Ho. an acaupovcmom - o coon uumccou .Fo>op we. we acouowocmvm - a .mummsucmcoo co mgosgo vgoucapm .oo.o Amo.o .NNo.. Aooo.. moo. No. ooo. ooo. oNo. Noo.- o-o moo 3-2-e.g. H-z-o-o. o.“ a AoNo.. Aoo.o “No.. Aoo.. No. oo.N No. Noo. No.- omo.- oo.- 42-2 oNoo .oo.o Aoo. .oNo.o .oNo.. Aooo.o .No.. oo. «o. oo.N oN. Noo.- Noo. ooo. oo.- ss-L moo 398 3H; A2; EN; EN; Sm; N¢.N oo. oo.o ooo. NN.- NN. oo. NN. m moo o .:.o ‘No goo .e-o so-» «o-o as-e o Loo oooooz ouoooN-ouoooo moo